LAWS OF NATURE IN ECONOMIC AFFAIRS 227 the recorded cycles are members of the same family, but among them there are no twins.'1 The same finding was reported by a student of the general economic history of Great Britain during the years A.D. 1790-1914: 'A reading of the evidence, statistical and qualitative, on the movements within the British economy in modern times, taken year by year, month by month, or week by week, leaves two enduring impressions. First, one is impressed with the uniqueness and variety of the story of economic life. The combinations of forces within the moving economy are, like those in political life, in an important sense always new and fresh. No year is quite like another year;2 and after a time one gets to know them like old friends. . . . Second, one is impressed with the solid reality of the cyclical pattern which steadily recurs, in Britain and then—gradually widening—through- out the World,3 from the end of the American Revolution to the outbreak of the First World War. No two cycles, of course, are quite the same; and one can trace, as well, certain long-period changes in the character of cycles. But it is evident that the whole evolution of Modern Society in the West occurred in a rhythmic pattern, which had consequences for social and political, as well as for economic, events.'+ This finding that the spectacle of likeness-in-difference is no peculiar feature of British nineteenth-century economic history, but is discernible in contemporary Western economic history as a whole, is endorsed by an impressive consensus of authoritative opinions. For instance, the authors of an essay in measuring business cycles find that 'Two conclusions emerge from this analysis. In the first place our tests, so far as they go, bear out the concept of business cycles as units of roughly concurrent fluctuations in many activities.5 In the second place they demonstrate that, although cyclical measures of individual series usually vary greatly from one cycle to the next, there is a pronounced tendency towards repetition in the relations among the movements of different activities in successive business cycles. Our analysis of hundreds of time series is sufficiently advanced to give us full confidence in these conclusions. Later monographs will demonstrate . . . that business-c$cle phenomena are far more regular than many historical-minded students believe/6 'Strictly speaking, every business cycle is a unique historical episode. . . . Business cycles differ in their duration as wholes and in the relative 1 Pigou, A. C.: Industrial Fluctuations, 2nd ed. (London 1929, Macmillan), pp. 12-13. z 'Each one [instance in any series of instances of a phenomenon: 'fluctuations, crises, booms, depressions'] is a historic individual and never like any other, either in the way it comes about or in the picture it presents' (Schumpeter, op. cit., vol. ir p. 34).—A.J.T. 3 According to Pigou, op. cit., p. n, industrial fluctuations became oecumenical in their range from about A.D. 1873 onwards. 'Bare as they are and short their span, the annals reveal a secular trend towards territorial expansion of business relations and a concomitant trend towards economic unity*, and this both within the United States and in the World at large, according to Mitchell, ibid., p, 446. Cp. p. 456.—A.J.T. * Rostow, W. W.: British Economy of the Nineteenth Century (Oxford 1948, Clarendon Press), pp. 31-32. s 'The swings of the different industries are not independent-----They are concordant in direction. We may fairly speak of common swings of expansion and contraction in the main body of industries taken separately, and not merely in the aggregate or average of industries. But . . . the amplitudes of the swings in different occupations are very far from concordant; some are much larger than others' (Pigou, A. C.: Industrial Fluctua- tions, 2nd ed. (London 1929, Macmillan), p. 13).—AJ.T. 6 Bums, A. F., and Mitchell, W. C.: Measuring Business Cycles (New York 1946, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.), pp. 488-91.