INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE BuKEAU OF Economic and Sociai, Inteixigence INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (MONTHLY BULLETIN OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL INTELLIGENCE) TABLE OF CONTENTS 1917 ROME PRINTING OFFICE OF THE INSTITUTE I918 Publications of the InternationaMnstitute of Agriculture. Publications for Sale. AOBoal Slogrli A. — MONTHLY PUBLICATIONS. sabecrlption noitb f 1. INTERNATIONAL CROP REPORT AND AGRICULTURAL STATISTICS {Bulletin — — Of Agricultural and Commercial Statistics) , published in English, French , Italian and Spanish, 8vo) Frs. 6 0.60 2. DOCUMENTARY I^EAFLETS (published in English, French, Italian and Spanish, 8vo) • • • 4 0,40 3. INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF THE SCIENCE AND Practice OF AGRICULTURE {Bulletin of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases) , pubUshcd in English, French, German, Italian and Spanish. (Each number consists of about 130 pages, 8vo) • x8 2. — 4. International Review of agricultural Economics (Bulletin of Economic and Social Intellificnct), published in English, French, Ger- man, Italian and Spanish. CEach number consists of about 100 pages, • Bvo)'. » »8 »•— Subscription lor all the abov^ mentioned Bulletins "36 B. — HALF-YEARLY [AND YEARLY PUBLICATIONS. I. Statistical NOTES on Cereals. Studies on yield, trade, consumption and prices, with rates of ocean freight published half-yearly in English, French, Italian and Spanish (Each number consists of about 130 pages, Bvo) . . Frs. 1.50 8. The International Trade in Feeding Stuffs, published yearly in English, French, Italian and Spanish. (Each number consists of about 50 pages, 8vo) • • '--O 3. The International Movement (Jf Fertilisers and Chemical Products useful to Agriculture, published yearly in English, French, Italian and Spanish. (Each number consists of about 90 pages, 8vo) • 1.50 C. — YEAR BOOKS. 1. A nnuaire International deStatistiqueAgricole pour 1910 (Iniernatio- iiaiYcarBookofAgriculturalStatistics,i9io). (igi2,Xl,VIII-f 327pages,8vo) Frs. 5.^ — DO. Vol.11, Years 1911-1912. (1914, XXXIV -f 624 pp. Bvo) • 5. — Do. Vol. Ill Years 1913-1914- {1915, XIvIV -f 78B pp. Bvo) • 5.— Do. Vol. IV Years 1915-1916.(191 7, I<+ 950 pp. Bvo) 10.— 2. annuaireInternationaldeI,6gislationAgricole, 1st Year, 1911. (Inter- national Year Book of Agricultural I'i*^o«3^ Bureau of Economic and Sociai, Inteu.igence W^^As>^^ INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (MONTHLY BULLETIN OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL INTELLIGENCE) TABLE OF CONTENTS 1917 ^ ROME PRINTING OFFICE OF THE INSTITUTE 1918 5^/7' THE INTERNATIONAIv INSTITUTE OF AGRICUIvTURE. Origin of the Institute and Summary of the International Treaty, The International Institute of Agriculture was established under the International Treaty of 7 June 1905, which was» ratified by forty govern- ments. Sixteen other governments have since adhered to the Institute. It is a government institution in which each country is represented by delegates. The Institute is composed of a General Assembly and a Permanent Committee. The Institute, always confining its attention to the international aspect of the various questions concerned, shall : (a) collect, study, and publish as promptly^ as possible, statistical, technical, or economic information concerning farming, vegetable and ani- mal products, trade in agricultural produce, and the prices prevailing in the various markets ; (b) communicate the above information as soon as possible to those interested ; (c) indicate the wages paid for farm work ; {d) record new diseases of plants which may appear in any part of the world, showhing the regions infected, the progress of the diseases, and, if possible, any effective remedies ; {e) study questions concerning agricultural co-operation, insurance, and credit from every point of view ; collect and publish information which might prove of value in the various countries for the organization of agri- cultural co-operation, insurance and credit ; (/) submit for the approval of the various governments, if necessary, measures for the protection of the common interests of farmers and for the improvement of their condition, utilising for this purpose all available sources of information, such as resolutions passed by international or other agricultural congresses and societies, or by scientific and learned bodies, etc. Permanent Committee OF THE International Institute of AoRicutTURE Presidint : Marquis Rappaele Cappelli, Delegate of Italy. Vice-President : M. Loms-Dop, Delegate of Prance. List ot the Delegates of the Permanent Committee : 13 U 15 j6 17 18 19 20 2t 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 ; 38 39 40 41 ♦2 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 SS 56 57 Abyssinia Argentine Republic. . . AOSTRIA Hdngakv Belgium Brazil Bulgaria Chile China Colombia Costa-Rica Cuba Denmark Ecuador Egypt France French West Africa. . Algeria Madagascar Morocco Tunis Germany Gt. Britain & Ireland. . Australia British India Canada Mauritius New Zealand Union of South Africa Greece Guatemala Italy Eritrea & It. Somal. Tripoli and Cirenaica Japan Luxemburg Mexico Montenegro Netherlands Dutch East Indies . . . Nicaragua Norway Ottoman Empire Paraguay Persia Peru Portugal Roumania Russia Salvador San Marino Serbia Spain Sweden Switzerland United States Urugu ay V I I I IV I III II I V V V IV V II I V V V V V I I III II II V IV IV IV V I IV IV I V lU V IV IV V rv I V IV V IV I I V V III I IV IV I V Prof. G. Cuboni, Director, Station of Plant Pathology, Rome Dr. OCTAVio Pineiro Sorondo. Cliev. V. de Pozzi, Government Cotincillor. O. BOLLE. M. STANaOFF. M. E. ViLLEGAS, Minister Plmipotentiary. Wang-Tseng-Sze. Don RuFO RuFFO, Principe della Scaletta. Marco Besso. M. A. JiARTiN RivERO, Minister Plenipotentiary. A. DE Oldenburg, Charge d'affaires. M. Miguel Valverde, Consul General. IvOUis-Dop, Vice-President of the Institute. Louis-Dop. Louis-Dop. Louis-Dop. Louis-Dop. I/)UIS-DOP. Dr. T. Mueller, Privy Councillor. Hon. William Erskine, Counsellor of the Embassy. Hon. William Erskxne. Hon. William Erskine. Hon. William Erskine. Hon. William Erskine. Hon. William Erskdte. Hon. William Erskine. M. Coromilas, Minister Plenipotentiary. G. Montefiore, Consul General for Guatemala. Marquis R. Cappelli, VicePres. of theCh.,Pres. of the Institute. SmNOOH iMAt, First Secretary of the Embassy. O. BoLLE, Delegate of Belgium. G. VoLPi, Minister Plenipotentiary. Baron W. B. R. de Welderen Rengers, Minister Plenip. Baron W. B. R. de Welderen Rengers. V. E. BiANCHi, Consul General. Dr. A. FjELSTAD, Counsellor to the Agricultural Department. Dr. Mehmed Djhmil Bey. A. DEL Gallo, Marquis of Roccagiovinb. Louis-Dop, Delegate of France. EuSEBio I,EAO, Minister Plenipotentiary. DE&iETRins C. Pennesco, Counsellor to the Legation. His Excell. G. Zabiello, Consul General for Russia. A. Blanchi Cagliesi, Vice-Consul. His Excell. L. Luzzatti, Minister of State. C. ScoTTi, Consul General for Serbia. Francisco Bilbao Sevilla, Agricultural Engineer. Baron C. N. D. de Bildt, Minister Plenipotentiary. M. DE Planta, Minister Plenipotentiary. Davtd Lubin. Dr. E. RoviRA, Consul. Secretary General: Prof. Carlo Dragoni. BXPI^ANATORY NOTE 1. The i>resent Table of Contents refers to the twelve numbers of the International Review of Agricultural Economics published from January to December, 191 7, and includes, therefore, all the articles and notes dealing with co-operation, insurance, credit and agricultural economy in general contained in these volumes. 2. The articles and notes relating to co-operation have been grouped in 2 i classes ; those dealing with insurance are divided into 0 classes ; those which deal i&ith credit into 9 classes ; and those which treat of agricultural economy in general into ij. A complete list of these classes precedes the table. In our classification we have followed the rule of single entry and placed un(ter only one heading those articles and notes which, from the nature of the subject treated, might appear in more than one group. As it is not in every case clear why an article or note has been assigned to one group rather than to another, the reader must be prepared to refefHo the several analogous groups in any one of which a particular article or note might appear. A dairymen's co-operative society, for example, might have as its object the protection of the general economic interests of dairy farmers as a class, or simHy the improvement of the methods of production, transport, and sale, or again the purchase and collective use of animals of the special dairy type. An article relating to such a society might appear under various head- ings, according as it dealt more particularly with one or other of tJtese objects. ■ 3. In each group the articles and notes have been subdivided by countries, following the aphabetical order. For each country the articles are arranged in the chronological order in which they were published. We have added a table giving the classification by countries. I. — CONTENTS BY SUBJECTS. CLASSIFIED LIST OF SUBJECTS I. — Co-operation and Association. I. General, studies. II. General, statistics. III. Central State institutions. IV. Federations of agricuetural co-operative societies. V. Central institutions of agricultural co-operative societies. VI. Co-operative credit societies. VII. Co-op er\tive societies for purchase and for purchase and sale. VIII. Co-operative productive societies. IX. Co-operative societies for production and sale or for sale. X. Co-operative dairies. XI. Collective farms. XII. Miscellaneous co-operative societies. XIII. Associations" for the protection of the general interests OF FARMERS. XIV. Associations to further the technical progress of agri- culture. XV. Associations concerned with live stock in general. XVI. Associations concerned with horned live stock. XVII. Bee-keeping associations. XVIII. Miscellaneous information relating to agricultural co- oper.\tion. XIX. Agricui,turai, congresses. XX. NON-AGRICUiyrURAL CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES OR ASSOCIATIONS. XXI. MlSCELLANTEOUS INFORMATION REI,ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN GENERAI,. XXII. Notices of pubucations. II. — Insurance and Thrift. I. Generae studies. II. Fire insurance. III. Haie insurance. IV. Live stock insurance. V. Insurance of eive stock raised for slaughter. VI. Insurance against agricueturae accidents. VII. Other branches of agricueturae insurance. VIII. MiSCEEEANEOUS INFORMATION REEATING TO AGRICULTURAL IN- SURANCE. IX. Notices of publications. III. - Credit. I. General studies on non-co-operative credit and the indebt- edness of landed property. II. Legislation. III. Intervention of the State and of public authorities. IV. Land credit. V. Agricultural credit. VI. Savings banks as credit institutions. VII. Bank system. VIII. Miscellaneous information. IX. Notices of publications. IV. — Agrarian Economy in General. I. GeneraIv studies. II. Fiscal system and agricui^ture. III. State as landowner. IV. Various forms of land tenure. V. The redistribution of lands and measures to prevent ex- cessive subdivision. VI. Agrarian reform in general. VII. Home colonization. VIII. Problems of hydraulics and forestry. IX. Trade and transport of agrarian products. X. Measures for the improvement op the conditions of country life. Cheap dwelling houses. Industries auxiliary to agriculture. XI. lyAND prices and REVENUES. ^ XII. Agricultural education (from the social point of view). XIII. Agricultural labour. XIV. State intervention in favour of agriculture. XV. Supply of agricultural produce and high cost of living. XVI. Miscellaneous information. XVII. Notices of publications. I. CO-OPERATIQN AND AvSSOCIATlON I. GBNERAIy vSTUDIES. Page 2 31-34 4 1-6 6 21-24 9 12-13 British India. I. — Co-operation in Travancore 2. — Progress of Agricultural Co-operation in IQ14-1915 . . 3. — The Progress of Agricultural Co-operation in India, in 1915-1916 4. — The Activity of the Co-operative Societies in 1915-1916 British West Indies. Co-operation in Antigua : an Object Lesson, by W. R. Dun- lop I 13-16 Canada. Recent Success of Agricultural Co-operation in Canada. . . 3 17-24 Germany. I. — Agricultural EcononiA' in the Kingdom of Saxony: I July 1914 to 30 June 1915 i 1-5 2. — Some Facts as to the Co-operative Movement ... 5 25-26 ITAI^Y. The Development of the Co-operative Movement in the A- bruzzi 9 20-20 Norway. The Agricultural Co-operative ^Movement 7 25-26 — M — N"> Page Russia. The Russian Co-operative Movement during the War ... 8 12-20 II. GENERAL STATlSTICvS. British India. Co-operative Societies in Bengal in 1915-1916 10 10-12 ITAI,Y. 1 . — The Statistics of the Catholic ySocial and Economic Institutions T i 26-26 2. — The Development of the Co-operative Movement in Italy according to Recent Statistical Data as to the " Lega Nazionale delle Cooperative " 6 6-12 3. — Co-operative Societies legally constituted on 31 De- cember 1915 9 16-18 4. — The Co-operative and Mutual Agricultural Societies in Italy on 31 December 1916 10 13-14 Japan. The Present Position of Co-operation in Japan. ..... 11 i-ii III. CENTRAL STATE INSTITUTIONS. British India. The Madras Provincial Co-operative Bank, Limited .... 2 34*35 IV. FEDERATIONS OF AGRICULTURAL CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES. Germany. 1 . — The General RaifEeisen Federation of Neuwied in 191 4- 1915 2 1-13 3 i-io 2. — The Federation of Polish Co-operative Societies in the Provinces of Posnania and West Prussia, in 191 4 . 6 24-28 iTAiY. 1 . — The Activity of the Office of Legal Advice of the " Le- ga Nazionale delle Cooperative " 3 29-30 2. — The Federations of the Catholic Rural Funds of the Provinces of Bologna, Reggio d'Emilia, Forli and Salerno in 1915-1916 5 ' 28-30 3. — The Constitution of " La Federazione delle Latterie So- ciali Cremonesi" 5 32-32 — 15 — N" Page 4. — The Position of Local Federations of Catholic Rural Funds on 31 December 1915 9 18-19 5. — The "Federazione Italiana dei Consorzi Agrari" in 1916 . . . . ■ 9 20-21 6. — The Formation of the "Federazione Nazionale delle Unioni Agricole " ' .'. . 9, 21-22 7. — The Position of the Provincial Federations of the Ca- tholic Rural Funds of Bologna, Florence and Pistoia 9 22-23 Russia The Central Co-operative Union of Flax Growers 7 14-21 United States. The California Federation of Farmers' Co-operative Market- ing Associations 12 51-52 V. CENTRAL INSTITUTIONS OF AGRICUIvTURATv CO-OPERATIVF SOCIETIES. British India. The ■ Madvura-Ramnad Central Co-operative Bank, Ivimited 11 12-13 Bui^garia. The Central Co-operative Bank of Bulgaria 7 1-7 ITAI,Y, The National Institute of Credit for Co-operation, the Insti- tute of Credit for Co-operative Societies and the Na- tional Bank of "Italian Rural Funds in 191 6 .... 7 8-13 VI. CO-OPBRATIVE CREDIT SOCIETIES. British India. The Activity of Co-operative Credit Societies in Ceylon in 1916 10 10 10 French Protectorate of Morocco. The Tlurift Societies 10 12-13 ITai,y. The Position of certain Popular Banks in 1 91 5 i 23-26 Regency op Tunis. Native Thrift Societies in 1 91 5 2 25-30 — iG — N" Page Russia. 1. — Mutual Credit Societies in Russia on i Jul}- 1915 . . . i 29-31 2. — Popular Co-operative Credit from 1 91 4 to 1 91 6 ... 4 19-27 SWITZERI.AND. The Swiss Union of Raiffeisen Funds 12 18-19 United States. North Carolina Rural Banks .4 34-35 VIT. CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES FOR PURCHASE AND FOR PURCHAvSE AND vSALE. Canada. I. — The Co-operative Sale of Wool 2 14-24 2. — Co-operative Trading in vSaskatchewan 9 13-14 ITAI^Y. The " Societa Anonima Cooper ativa per I'Esportazione dei Prodotti Agricoli " of Jesi in 1915-1916 3 28-29 United States. The Co-operative Purchase of Live Stock in Wisconsin . . 4 31-34 VIII. CO-OPERATIVE PRODUCTIVE SOCIETIES. Great Britain and Irei^and. An Irish Co-operative vSociety for Growing Wheat 7 24-2*5 Russia.^ The Finnish Superintending Societies in the Years 1913-1915 3 32-33 Switzerland. The Co-operative Cornmill at Leman 9 24-24 United States. I. — The Development of the Co-operative Associations controlling Dairy Production in the United States from 1966 to 191 6 2 37-39 2. — The California Peach Growers' Association in 191 6 1917 ■ 9 25-25 — 17 — N° Page IX. CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES FOR PRODUCTION AND SALE, OR FOR vSxlLE. Austria. The Co-operative Oilmills in Dalmatia 3 11-16 Canada. I. — Co-operative Stock Marketing in Alberta 9 14-15 2. — The Co-operative Marketing of Agricultural Produce 10 1 g ITAI,Y. lya Federazione Apistica Italiana 5 31-32 Russia. I. — The Egg Trade and Co-operation in Ru.ssia .... 9 7-1 1 2. — The Co-operative Sale of Tobacco 10 14-16 United States. 1 . — The Co-operative Marketing of Live Stock in Wisconsin i 31-32 2. — Farmers' Co-operative Elevators in Minnesota ... 8 i-ii 3. — The Co-operative Production and Sale of Raisins in California 10 16-18 4. — The Essentials of Successful Co-operative Fruit and Vegetable Canneries 11 15-17 X. CO-OPERATIVE DAIRIES. Itai,y. Collective Dairies 4 7-18 Russia. Finnish Co-operative Dairies in 1915 5 33-34 Spain. I. — The First Co-operative Cheese Factory 6 1-5 2. — The Co-operative Dairy of the " Ca.sa de Ganaderos " of Saragossa 7 26-27 United vStates. A Co-operative Cheese Manufacturing and Marketing As- sociation in Tillamook County in Oregon 12 20-24 2 — i8 — N" ■ Page XI. COI.LECTIVE FARJklS. ITAXY. 1, — The Collective Farm of San Giovanni in Croce .... 3 27-28 2. — Facilities for the Leasing of Domanial Lands by Co- operative Societies 12 13-13 3. — Collective Farms in the Province of Parma 12 14-16 XII. MISCFLLANEOUS CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES. France. I. — A New Syndicate for Mechanical Agriculture .... 2 36-37 2. — ^The Co-operative Societies for the Cultivation of A- bandoned Lands and the Reconstruction of Des- troyed Villages 7 22-24 Great Britain and Irei^and. Co-operative Fishing in the Aran Islands 12 9-13 ITAI.Y. A Co-operative Association among Owners and Usufructories of Woods 12 17-18 Russia. 1 . — Co-operative Supply and Production of Agricultural Machines i 2. — The Position and the Activity of the Grain Elevators of the Government and the Railway Companies ... 3 XIII. ASSOCIATIONS FOR THE PROTECTION OF THE GENERAL INTERESTS OF FARMERS. Bei,gium. The Activity of the Belgian Boerenbond in 1 91 5 5 Spain. The Association of the Agriculturists of Spain and its Work i SWITZERI.AND. The Peasants' "C» nion and Peasants' Secretariat in 1916 . . 6 — 19 — N° Page United States. I. — The Activity of the Jewish Agricultiiral and Industrial Aid Societ5'-in 1916 5 35-36 2. — The American Society of Equity 6 28-29 XTV. AvSvSOCIATlONS^TO FURTHER THE TECHNICAL PROGREvSS OF AGRICULTURE. Denmark. The Activity of the Royal Society of Danish Agriculture in 1915-1916 5 9-14 Germany. Housewives' Agricultural Associations and their Activity . i 20-21 Great Britain and Irei6-73 XIV. STATE INTERVENTION IN FAVOUR OF AGRICULTURE. Great Britain and Irei^and. The Scottish Land Court in 191 5 . . .* 6 64-74 SWITZERI^AND. Federal Aid to Swiss Agriculture 7 83-86 1 XV. SUPPLY OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCE AND HIGH CO.ST OF LIVING. Canada. Cold Storage in Canada 12 .53-65 39 Page Great Britain and Ireland. I. — The Corn Production Act, 1917 10 67-71 2. — Further Provisions of the Corn Production Act 191 7 12 74-78 ITAI,Y. Recent Measures for Developing the Growing of Cereals . . 7 80-81 Russia. ^ Food Control Conuuittees 12 82-83 United States. Federal Food Control Act 12 83-84 « »XVI. MISCELLANEOUS INFORI^IATION. Argentine. The Leasing of the Domain Lands 11 81-82 France. I. — The Department for Civil and Military Vegetable Gardens 3 ii8-iig 2. — The Restoration of Agriculture in the Invaded Depart- ments 9 79-81 3. — The Technical Re-education in Estabhshments de- pending on the Ministry of Agriculture of Men Muti- lated in the War 10 56-66 ITALY. 1 . — ■ Rules for granting the Temporary Use of Agricultural Machines 2. — -National Charity for the Orphans of Peasants killed in the War 3. — An Important Scheme for the Foundation of a Pro- vincial Institution of vSocial Aid 4. — A General Commissariat for Food Consumption- . . . 5. — -The Protection given by the Province of Florence to the Orphans of Peasants killed during the War . . 6. — - The New Organization of the Ministry of Industry, Commerce and Labour . 2 II 8-1 20 2 121-123 2 123-125 4 109-110 4 110-112 7 81-82 — 40 — Page Russia. The Settlement of Kirghiz Nomads on the Steppes of Tur- kestan 4 114-115 United Statics. Overtime in the Fruit and Vegetable Canning and Paeking Industry of Oregon 2 125-126 XVII. NOTICES OP PUBIylCATlONS. Austria. I. — Agrar-Compass Jahr- und Adressbuch der oesterrei- chischen Landwirtschaft » . . . . 6 86-86 2. — WiTTSCHiEBEN (Dr. Otto) : Die Zwangsversteigerun- gen land- und forstwittschaftlicher Grund.stiieke in Steiermark 1903-1912 8 85-85 3. — STrakorch (Dr. Siegfried H. C.) : Die Grundlagen der Agrarwirtschaft in Oesterreich. Bine Haudels- und Producktionspolitische Untersucliung 8 85-86 Austria and Hungary. FeiFai^ of the island. The asso- ciation is affiliated to the Antigua Agricultural and Commercial Society and to the Antigua Onion Growers' Association, but this does not imply general distribution of responsibilities. The Lime Growers' Association, which is at the present time in process of formation, has, it appears, for its principal object, the establishment of a small but profitable green lime trade wih New York, supplementary to that of Dominica which has assumed big dimensions of recent years. Antigua, it is supposed, profiting by the experiences of Dominica and guided by her own knowledge of the value of combined action, intends to estab- lish a central grading depot and to make beforehand, if possible, special arrangements in regard to freight facilities. While this is commendable, it is a question whether the production of limes in Antigua will ever attain large proportions. The present account of co-operation in Antigua would not be complete without some reference to the Indian corn or maize industry of that island. It had been felt for some time that the West Indian islands should produce more corn and import less. Antigua, as might be expected, was the first to lead the way to giving effect to this idea. The principal difficulty was that, to keep, corn must be dried. This would necessitate the establishment of a kiln-drying plant, and this the Antigua govern- ment decided to do. In May 1914 the establishment was opened, its efficiency having been previously demonstrated. Antigua kiln-dried corn had been found to be as good if not better than the imported American product. The terms on which local deliveries are accepted by the granary are as follows : (i) the co-operative plan whereby a first payment of 2s. 6d. per bushel of shelled grain is made to growers, to be followed by a distribu- tion of the surplus profits of the undertaking after paying all expenses and deducting 25 per cent, as the profit of the granary ; (2) the purchase of corn for cash at the rate of 3s. 6d. per bushel of shelled grain ; (3) the kiln- drying of corn for which a charge not exceeding 6d. per bushel is made. Arrangements were made later for the erection of a meal-making ma- chine. The effect of the establishment of this granary was to increase largely the area under Indian corn in the island. It cannot be said, however, that so far the granary has been a financial success, nor is it likely to be until corn is produced in large quantities in excess of the immediate local require- ments. At present it is in the nature of a governement insurance of corn growing and from that point of view should at least inspire confidence. In connection with corn growing it may be noted that during the present year an attempt to encourage the industry was made by holding a maize show. This function was highly successful and may be expeceted to have the desired result. ;,. v , In concluding this review of events in Antigua, we may^the more appreciate their importance by considering for a moment their external as part from their internal effects. The Antigua Sugar Factory was distinctly l6 WEST INDIES - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION a pioneer or experimental project. Its promotion involved heav>' respon- sibilities on the part of the originators. It proved a success, however, with the result that a few years after its establishment another and similar fac- tory was erected in the neighbouring island of St. Kitts. These factories in their turn have served to encurage greater centrahzation of recent years in Barbados. Turning to the Antigua Onion Growers' Association we are able to re- cord a most striking external effect. Last year an affiliated association was formed in Montserrat and a similar one in the Virgin Islands, while Nevis, if it has not an association, is endeavouring to develop its onion industry on similar co-operative Hues to those followed in Antigua. It will be seen therefore that a great deal of importance attaches to the study of the economic conditions obtaining in Antigua. It is an island which, though its prospects now are good, has been subject to adversities; but combined action in the right direction has won. Even the fortunes of the most flourishing colonies may suddenly take a turn in the wrong direction — it may be through unavoidable causes or from unpreparedness to meet avoid- able ones : in any case co-operation in Antigua provides a useful object lesson that should not be neglected even by the most affluent of agricultural communities. MISCELLANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. DENMARK. THE GEXERAI, UNION OF CO-OPERATIVE CONSUMERS' ASSOCIATIONS IN1915 (i). Following on our previous remarks regarding co-operative consumers' societies in Denmark we give the essential results of the activity in 1915 of the General Union of these societies. On 31 December 1914, 1,407 associations • — almost all of those exist- ing in Denmark — belonged to the General Union. Their members num- bered 219,492. A year later, on 31 December 1915, eighty-one associations, numbering 12,636 members, had acceded to the union. The following figures show the progress of the movement since 1896. 1896 1901 1903 1905 1907 1909 1911 1913 1914 1915 Number of Asscciations belonging to the Union 310 684 1,029 1,189 1,224 1,286 1.359 1,407 1,488 Number of their Members 90,972 115,872 143,031 168,696 173,808 181,326 194.337 219,492 232,128 Amount of Turnover in Millions of crowns (2) 4.2 13-5 19.8 26.3 364 41.7 48.8 62.0 69.6 71-5 The reserve funds of the associations which were 350,000 crowns on 31 December 1901, amounted on 31 December 1905 to 1,100,000 crowns; on 31 December 1910 to 2,775,000 crowns ; in 1912 to 3,657,000 crowns ; in 1913 to 3,987,000 crowns ; in 1914 to 4,276,000 crowns ; on 31 December 1915 to 4,583,000 crowns. (i) Note sent by our correspoudeiit in Copenhagen. {2) I crown = about is i y^dat par. i8 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The General Union is not concerned only with trade but devotes also considerable activity to industry. The following figures indicate its oper- ations in its different spheres of action. Commercial Activity. (Value of operations in millions of crowns). Section for colonial provisions » )> manufactures » » edge-tools 1) 11 grains » » trade in wood » » large merchandise » » wines » » packing » » cycles Total 1915 72.4 50-4 38.5 5-2 4-9 5.0 4-2 4.1 2.7 0.2 0.2 0.6 0.4 0.6 0.3 6.0 6.0 0.3 0-3 57-5 1913 Industrial A ctivity . (Value of operations in millions of crowns). Roasting of coffee Manufacture of chocolate » » sugar » » tobacco & cigars » » ropes » » soap » » chemicals (technical) » » knitting I) » margarine Spice mills Section for com Packing Total 2.9 0.8 0.4 i.o 0.6 I.I 0,2 0.2 6.1 0.4 0.2 I.I 15.0 1914 2.8 0.7 0.3 0.8 05 1.0 0.2 0.2 4-7 0.4 0.2 0.8 12.6 It will be seen that of late years the increase in the value of operations has been distributed over almost all branches of activity, and that the profits, INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 19 which in 1912 were 2,846,000 crowns, rose in 1913 to 3,048,000 crowns, in 1914 to 3,825,000 crowns, and in 1915 to 5,005,000 crowns. In terms of the percentage of the figure representing the business done, that is of the value of the purchases giving a right to a share of dividends, the associations belong- ing to the union received 5.5 per cent, in 1912, 5.5 per cent, in 1913, 6 per cent, in 1914, and 7 per cent in 1915. We will conclude by reproducing the balance-sheets of the union, dated i January 1916, 1915 and 1914. Balance Sheets of the General Union . (in millions of crowns). Credit. Stock of merchandise In hand Inventory .... Properties Credit Total Debit. Co-operative societies' account Reserve funds' » Dividends » Debit » for loans Insurance » (against lowering of prices) Reduction in value of buildings Insurance account Insurance renewal account , Insurance account (against disturbance of activity) . lyoans on properties Various creditors Carried over from last year Net excess Total . . . igi6 1914 0.93 0.80 0.78 4-58 4.27 3-99 0.23 0.18 0.15 1.99 2-34 2.90 0.57 0.27 0.20 350 3.50 3.00 O.IO O.IO O.IO 0.50 0.50 0.50 0.30 O.IO — 0.99 1. 00 1.32 6.37 3.81 3.65 0.52 0.04 0.04 5.00 3.83 3-05 25-58 20.74 19.68 20 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION GER3IANY. HOUSEWIVES' AORICUT^TURAE ORGANIZATIONS AND THEIR ACTIVITY. — Boehiu, Elisabeth, in Blatter fiir Genossenachajtswesen. Berlin, ib September 1916. The aim of the first agricultural association of housewives in East Prussia, which was founded nearl}^ twenty years ago and composed of town and countrv' members, was to inculcate in its members the princi- ples of a sound economic education, and to institute an office for the sale to town housewives of fresh country' provisions. Countrywomen were thus enabled to sell their produce more profitably than heretofore while the large towns found themselves more amply and more economically provided with foodstuffs. The selling offices further affect agriculture in that they induce those interested in it to increase the cultivated area and to emplo3' the soil scien- tifically, and in that they allow a large sale of small quantities of vegeta- bles and fruit produced on distant farms. At present there is at least one housewives' association in each district and a selling office in every small town. For the whole province the turn- over of these organizations amounted in 1915 to 1,330,000 marks (i). There are also twenty associations in West Prussia, thirteen in Pomerania, twelve in Silesia and as mauA' in Schleswig-Holstein and in the pro\dnce of Saxon^'. These have, following the example of East Prussia, grouped themselves in provincial federations which have adhered to a Prussian provincial federation. In all the other Prussian provinces and German States a series of these associations are found, so that there are altogether more than 120 of them founded on similar bases and working as free socie- ties. This free form seems to suit the organizing activit}^ of women better than the co-operative form, which invariably exacts a larger measure of work and of responsibility than housewives are able to supply. In spite of the unsuccessful experience at Hildesheim of a housewives' association organized as a co-operative society, new attempts in this direction have recentl}- been made in Hanover, which is the province par excellence of co- operative organization. At Hanover itself, at Liinebourg and at Osna- briick housewives' associations and selling offices, which are co-operative in form, have been instituted. The financial results of the enterprise cannot as 3"et be estimated. It is however certain that when several selling offices are established the turnover of the smallest towns increases, while on the other hand the gene- ral costs diminish. The free associations at first deduct 10 per cent, for general costs, but subsequenth' often effect a reduction to 8 per cent. It is found that the latter percentage will allow the maintenance of itinerant instructors, and the institution of establishments for making jams and pre- (1) I mark = about 11 3/4 d. at par. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 21 ser\-es and of others for hatching eggs, as well as grants to social enterprises and to the daughters of poor members for their instruction in domestic economy. In their monthly meetings the town and countn,- members discuss prices together, and thus for the first time townswomen are able to parti- cipate in fixing prices. The shops of the associations have distinguished themselves during the war by maintaining fair prices, often lower than those which obtain in markets. ITALY. r. AGRICUI^TURAI, CO-OPERATION AND SOCIAL ASSISTANCE OF PEASANTS.— La Cooperazionc ItalianU; Milan, No. 1212, 6 October 1916. The Congregation of Charit> recently took important decisions in favour of promoting agricultural co-operation in the management of the lands owned by charitable institutions, and of ensuring to peasants habit- ually emplo3'ed on the congregation's own farms a minimum of social assis- tance correspondent to modern needs. The provisions in <]uestion are courageous and are destined to produce the best results. The}' could eas- ily be adopted by the administrators of all charitable institutions which own rural land, and several congresses have already declared themselves to this effect (i). We think therefore that it "nnll be intercbting to describe them. Above all the council of the congregation affirmed the dut}' of pubhc administrations owning rural property to endeavour to raise the level of the intellectual, moral and enconomic life of the peasants working on their land. The council was further of the opinion that the best means o* doing (i) In Bologna, on the 15th of last October in a meeting of the representatives of labour or- ganizations, held to discuss the letting of rural lands owned by charitable institutions ar.d the r Jations between agricultural and labom co-operative societies, an order of the day was approv- ed, which affirmed thj power of the public administrators of the province to give a preference in litting agreem nts to the co-operative societies, particularly to the local federation which was th;ir b;st known nucL^us, and which invited the delegates of the public administrations of the labour organizations to nominate a mixed technical commission charged a) to formulate " general regulations for letting " which should legitimately" safeguard public interests and the particular interests of the contracting parties ; 6) to act permaraentlj- in an arbitrating capac- ity in order to prevent ditferences which might arise as to such leases. The congress further expressed a desire that the provincial federation should oblige its adherent co-operative soci- eties to become more and more doselj' connc-cted with the organizations exis'ing specificallj- for collective pro\ isioning and sale of the articles and commodities necessary to agriculture and derived from it (agricultural un'ons, autonomous commtmal 'nstitutions, co-opetative consumers' societies, etc.), thus gradually eliminating the ustless niiddkmtnwho burden production as much as consumption. See in this connection La Cooperazionc Itahana, Milan, No. 1215, 27 October 1916. 22 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION this was to entrust the management of lands to the co-operative societies formed by the agricultural labourers, whenever these gave proof of an ade- quate technical and financial capacit5^ In order to guarantee that co-operative societies undertaking the man- agement of the congregation's farms would be faithful to the principle of co-operation, and that their technical, book-keeping and economic duties would be regularly discharged, these societies were advised to join the Feder- ation of Agricultural Co-operative Societies which has offices at Milan and which proposes to aid agricultural co-operation in the matter of technique and bookkeeping, financing it and assisting the societies' collective pur- chases and sales. Further, in order to aid peasants working on farms let to individu;ils, the council resolved : i) To render obligatory the contracts as to settlements and the labour agreements in force in the respective districts, especially as regards : a) minimum wages in kind and money and in shares of profits ; h) hours of labour and of rest ; e) guarantees and insurances in cases of illness, accident, disablement and old age ; d) the registration of contracts of settlement and labour bj^ employ- ment offices ; e) the decision of disputes between employers and peasants by submit- ting these to the commission of conciliation and arbitration annexed to the employment offices. 2) The council resolved that persons farming lands in districts in which special settlement contracts and labour agreements were not in force, should appl}^ the most favourable conditions as to hours and wages - both in money and in kind — which were locally customary. They should annuall}^ deposit with the administration of the congre- gation a copy of the contract made with ever}^ labouring family, which should conform to a model furnished b}' the administration. The guarantees must be given to the peasants, to provide for the cases of sickness, accident, disablement and old age, which we have already men- tioned under letter c). Disputes arising between employers and peasants, and outside the ter- ritorial sphere of the arbitrating commission, should be submitted for ami- cable settlement to the president of the congregation's technical office. The share of the administration in the costs of these provisions for the peasants will be : i) A quarter of the premium for insurance against accidents. 2) One lira for each peasant registered or to be registered by the National Thrift Fund (Cassa Nazionale di Providenza), such lira to dimi- nish that minimum share of the registration fee which will be chargeable to the peasant. 3) A third of the premium for the insurance against fire of the moveables, implements, clothes and food of a peasant, the other two thirds remaining chargeable to the employer and to the peasant, respectively. The INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 23 total sum of these contributions, estimated for each propert'>^ should be taken into account at the time of the expert valuation of the dues burdening rent, and should be part of the sum annually deducted from these dues, to the credit of the employer. All the above provisions will be comprised in the lists of stipulations as to properties let in the current year ; and since their effects can be realized rapidly and can reach a large number of peasants, the council decided to invite employers enjoying current leases to apply the conditions which fa- vour peasants from the beginning of the coming agricultural year. Finally to complete these provisions the council decided : i) to vote 600 liras (i) to the employment offices for peasants, tak- ing such sum from the reserve on the balance-sheet of 1916, and to include a Uke contribution in the budgets for future years ; 2) to found an itinerant chair of domestic economy, with the object of giving rules for rational housekeeping to families labouring on the lands of the administration ; 3) to promote and subsidize enterprises tending to the spread of cul- ture, such as evening and Sunday courses of elementary instruction in the farms, circulating libraries, courses of technical instruction, etc. 4) to occasion an agreement with other charitable enterprises own- ing rural lands, for the purpose of instituting an agricultural inspectorate which will see that the rules stipulated in leases in the interests of peasants are effectively applied, that the laws of hygiene and sanitation are observed, that there is compulsory education, etc. * * * 2. THE POSITION OF CERTAIN POPULAR BANKS IN 1913. — Credito e Cooperazione, oigan of the Assodaztone fra le Banchc Pnpnlan, Rome, No. iq, 1 October 1916. The Agricultural Bank of Mantua (2). — The report accompanying the balance-sheet for 1915 (45th year) of this bank opens bj^ drawing at- tention to the rapid decline in deposits in the first months of the year — from eighteen and a half millions at the end of 1914 to fourteen millions in the following May — ; and to their no less rapid increase after the beginning of the war, so that in October 1915 they again reached eighteen millions and in December twenty-one and a half millions. Thus in the first half- year there were difficulties due to the diminution of resources, and other difficulties in the second half-year due to the plenty of money, much of which was deposited only on a precarious title. These difiiculties, and the necessity of being prepared to face the eventual withdrawal of part of the deposited sum, showed the bank's administrators the path they must fol- low. In the first place securities were prudently reduced and then the (i) I s = 1. 261 1 liras at par. • (2) La Banca Agricola Mantovana. 24 INFORMATION REIvATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION normal course of dealing with them was resumed, such investments being preferred as were not only safest but also most readily realized. The re- sults of this prudent management are evident in the balance-sheet, of which the principal figures can be resumed as follows : Shareholder's property : 1,262,704 liras — including 443,000 Uras in share capital and ordinary reserve, 136,000 Uras in repaid shares and profits, and a special fund of 683,000 hras. Deposits : 21,453,391 liras — including small savings amounting to more than ten millions, five millions of ordinary savings deposits, more than five millions on current account and 776,000 liras in interest-bearing bonds. Altogether resources amount to about twenty-two and three quarter millions, as to which sum the following investments should be noted : securities on 31 December, ten and a half million; the bank's title-deeds, more than seven million ; advances remaining, four million hras. Net profits amounted to 65,784.50 liras; and of them 18,767 liras were assigned to the shareholders, namely 5 per cent, on their shares which is the maxi- mum allowed by the by-laws, and 37,149 liras to the fund destined to guaran- tee values, while the rest was placed at the council's disposition for the employees' thrift fund, and for renumerations, allocations, etc. The Popular Mutual Bank of Teramo (i). — This is one of the oldest establishments for popular mutual credit, having originated in 1881. The difficulties which it had to overcome in 1915 were not trifling. They did not however prevent it from developing an activity beneficent both to the city and to its own clients : it placed large means at the disposal of the commune for the acquisition of grain ; it repaid to depositors in less than ten months a million and a half liras, and it invested in national loans — all this without neglecting local needs and those of small commerce, in the interests of which the rate of discount was always kept within moderate limits — ; and finally it strengthened its banking business by a consider- able sum of net profits. To resume the bank's enterprise in this year we will give the following figmes from its balance-sheet : The total capital amounted to 634,837 liras, including 150,000 liras of capital in shares (3,000 shares of 50 liras each held b}' 1,234 sharehold- ers), 75,000 liras of ordinary reserve, 397,000 liras of extraordinary re- serve and a reserve of 13,000 liras to provide against oscillations in values. Deposits on current account amounted to 146,000 liras and savings deposits to 2,283,463 liras. There was a reduction of 789,000 liras in the savings deposits, as compared with the preceding year. Not only the state of war, but also the diminished remittances of emigrants, the local agricultural crisis caused by the failure of the harvest and the vintage which obliged agriculturists to withdraw their deposits, and finally the issue of the national loans, were responsible for the decline in saving. (i) I,a Banca Mutua Popolare di Teramo. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 25 Securities at the end of the 3^ear gave a balance of 2,494 bills for 2,423,336. liras, including 2,022,231 liras on bills expiring within three months and 401,105 liras on those expiring later. Bills discounted in 1915 numbered 10,972 and were for more than eleven million liras. The diminution in the discounts effected, as compared with 1914, was 42,000 liras. Dishonoured bills for the year are represented in the balance-sheet by only 23,000 liras. The title deeds of the bank's propert}" amounted to 678,000 liras, ' 660,000 liras thereof being invested in treasury bonds. As regards the profit and loss account, the net profits amounted to 61,000 liras, of which sum 11,887 liras was assigned to the shareholders at the rate of 4 liras a share, 43,000 liras went to augment different reserve funds, 2,000 liras was granted to beneficent objects and 2,000 liras to the industrial school. Tlie Popular Mutual Bank of Verona (i). — This is one of the oldest popular banks in Venetia, having been founded in 1867, that is at the beginning of I/uigi IvUzzatti's organization of a propaganda of popular credit. It has alw^ays remained faithful to its early principles, and thaiiks to prudent administration it has attained morally and materially to a lead- ing position. lyike kindred institutions it felt last year the effects of the country's economic crisis as determined by political events : the sums deposited in this bank were at first reduced, and later, when calm had re- turned to the market, it had to find the best investments for the consider- able sum which the plentiful return of deposits placed at its disposal However it was able to overcome transitory embarassments, by rediscount- ing largeh' and frequentl}' the securities of similar banks, by subscribinj5 to the national loans, or by reducing the rate of interest paid on deposits of each category in order to lessen their superabundance. By such mea- sures the hard times were successfully passed. The figures on the balance- sheet are most satisfactory and show the institution's flourishing condi- tion. We will quote the principal of them : The shareholders' property was 756,470 liras of which 484,308 liras represents the capital (13,453 shares of 36 liras each) and 272,162 liras the reserve. Deposits amounted to twelve and a half million liras, two million on current account and ten and a half in savings deposits. The increase shown by this item as compared with 1914 is of 1,400,000 liras. Securities held at the end of the year gave a balance of 4,236,092 liras, showing a diminution of 800,000 liras as compared with the preceding year's balance. We have abready noticed the reasons for a limitation of activity, and these also affected the year's profits. . The bank holds title-deeds of its property for 2,373,873 liras, all offer- ing the surest guarantee and being readily realizable. The net profits amounted to 79,392 liras ; of which 30,000 liras went to augment the reserve, 24,205 liras were assigned to shareholders at the (i) I,a Banca Mulua Popolare di Verona. 3 26 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION rate of 5 per cent, on their paid-np capital, and the remainder was divided among the council and the employees. The profit and loss account shows that this bank also spent during the year more than 3,000 liras on beneficent objects. 3. THE STATISTICS OF THE CATHOLIC SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS. — Azione Sociale, orgRV. of the Social and Economic Union of Catholic Italians, Fatnza, No. 14 November 1916. The Unione Economico-Sociale jra i CaUoUci Italiani is compiling general statistics as to social and economic associations in Itaty. With this object it has already circulated a special form of questions, asking the name of a given society, its site and address, data as to its constitution — whether legal or merely actual — , the number of its members (including those under arms), its collective property on 31 December 1915, its re- ceipts in 1 91 5, the assessment of members, the assessments or premiums received in 1915, its expenses in 1915. .Societies of the following categories are the objects of the enquiry' : mutual aid societies, mutual insurance societies (of live stock and against fire and hail), agricultural unions for collective purchase, consumers' co-op- erative societies, labour and producing co-operative societies, co-operative societies for agriculture and collecdve letting and for building popular dwellings, and trade organizations (including offices of labour and secre- tariats of the people and of emigration). National federations adhering to the Union have also been invited to supply data relative to 1915 or of later date, in order that a complete pic- tture of Catholic economic organization may be obtained. In due time we willfshow the chief conclusions drawn from these important statistics. RUSSIA. I. CO OPERATIVE SUPPLY AND PRODUCTION OP AGRICULTURAL MACHINES. 1) KoBA.itB.JI. (Koval v. D.): Co-oPERATrvE Trade in AGRicuLTtjRAL Machines in Ma- iiiiiHa B73 cejlL-CKOMij Xo3HiicTB'fe (The Machine in Agriculture) N°. i, Kiev, 15 Januarj' 191 6 ; 2) JlEniEBOii M. (Dechevoj M.): The Agrictxltuk.al Machine Industry in Russia, ibid : Nos. 10 and 11, 31 May and 15 June 1916 ; 3) Zt-oj M. (D-oj M.) : The Dissemin.'vtion of Agricultural Machines and Implements BY Co-oper.'^tive Credit, ibid : Nos. 14 and 15-16, 15 August and i and 30 September 1916. The collective supply of agricultural machines and implements in Rus- sia is now chiefly undertaken by the co-operative credit unions, who have INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 27 been empowered by a statute of 1895, having reference to 1905, to conduct such enterprise. The number of co-operative credit unions who take upon themselves the task of providing agricultural machines for the rural popu- lation increases year by year, as does the sum of money which they thus employ. These facts appear from the following table : Number of Co-operative Supply Associations Sums they spend on buying Agricultural Machines 1910. 1911. 1912. 1913- 1914. 3,200,000 roubles 4,900,000 6,346,000 0,638,000 14,000,000 " Last year co-operative suppty was responsible for lo.S per cent, of the whole trade in machines. The sums which the co-operative unions lend to their members for the purchase of agricultural machines vary in amount. According to an en- quiry made by the Distribution of Agricultural Machines the following sums were lent with this object in 191 2 by the co-operative credit unions and the savings and loan funds to their members : by 7,754 co-operative credit unions. » 1,558 savings and loan funds. . in all. . 8,635,921 roubles (i) 3.029,850 » 11,665,771 Of the 3,000 co-operative unions (20 per cent, of all the credit unions), which in 1914 undertook the supply of agricultural machines, only 723 were combined in the eleven following federations of co-operative unions : (i) I rouble cf gold = about 2S i ^ rf at psr. 28 INFORMATION REI^ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Year of Foundation Number of Co-operative Unions combined Sums spent on' Agricultural Machines of Kiev Jekaterinburg . Melitopol. . . Berdjansk . . Tersk .... Nikolaiev . . JekaLerinoslav Nijni-Novgorod Kiibanj. ... Zlatoust . . . Blagodarinsk . 1907 1907 1903 1901 1911 1915 1911 1911 1911 1911 1907 190 74 34 25 86 9 60 106 23 20 27 140,000 roubles 333.760 79,484 55.690 10,438 20,012 26,829 59.278 93.747 73.959 723 975,197 roubles The co-operative supply of agricultural machines has developed most importantly in the east in the federations of Jekaterinburg and Zlatoust, and in the south in the federation of Kiev. The amount of the sums spent on agricultural machines is not alway directly related to the number of single co-operative unions which a federation combines, a circumstance to be explained by the fact that unfederated co-operative unions also supply their demand for agricultural machines by availing themselves of the ser- vices of the federations as central purchasing organizations. This practice becomes increasingly prevalent as the co-operative instinct grows and the co-operative unions spread. In 1914 the co-operative federations were responsible for seven per cent, of all the co-operative supply of agricultural machines. All signs point to a ver^^ notable increase of this percentage in the near future ; for the whole course of co-operative supply tends indubi- tably to the formation of co-operative federations and thus assures the fruitful development of the co-operative supply of agricultural machines. It is symptomatic in the case of several federations — those of Kiev, Je- katerinburg, Tersk, Nijni-Novgorod and Kuban j — that the}' are not content merely to supph^ machines, but wish also to teach the scientific use of these, after they have come into the hands of the peasants, and thus to bring about good methods of farming. To this end they engage agricultural experts, set up stations where advice may be had as to agriculture, initiate co-operative tmions for machines and so forth ; all of which measures are calculated, like the machines themselves, to intensify and improve agricul- ture on the peasants' farms. An effort which is now being made by the co-operative unions to aim INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION at the production of machines themselves may hold much promise for the future ; for the import from foreign countries of machines, on which annual- h' a sum of 63,800,000 roubles was expended, has been almost stopped. The co-operative federations in Jekaterinburg and Melitol should be mentioned in this connection as pioneers. They have already worked out plans for establishing machine factories which have the necessary strong backing. A co-operative factory which turns out 1,000 corn-winnow- ing machines a year is now at work in Melitopol. In view of the present large demand for machines it may be taken as certain that this factory will soon be followed bv others. 2. MUTUAL CREDIT SOCIETIES IN RUSSIA ON i JULY 1915. Cbo3:i> Ba-iaHCOBi, OrbmecTB'B BaaiiMHaro Kpe;3;HTa ;],'feHCTByK)in;HX'i> bb Poccii-i na i Iiojih 1915 TOjia. — MiiHiicxepcTBO OHHancoBi,. (Hn;i,aHie Oco6eHHoii KanuejinpiH no Kpe;;HTHOH HacTii) (Collection of Summarized Financial Statements of the Mutual Credit Societies operating in Russia, showing their Condition on 1 Jtily 1915) Special Oflfice for Credit Business, Petrograd, P. P. Sojkin, 1916 (folio) 39 pp. We take the followdng most prominent data from the half yearl}' report, based on figures, which has been issued by the special office for providing credit of the Ministr}' of Finance, as to the position and acti- vity of existing credit societies on i July 1915. The credit societies which were modelled on the Brussels " Union de credit " in Petrograd in 1864, and of which the first fifty years of life were honoured at the appropriate time in our Review (i), ntmibered 1,179 ^^ ^^^ the Russian State on i July 1915. Thirty-one of them were in Petrograd, eight in Moscow, about 170 in the capital towns of governments and provinces, and 970 in those of districts and in small countr}^ places. Their existence in the last named — the circumstance that these societies are foiind even in small market towns — has particular interest for us ; for thus they enter into business relations wdth the rural population, who are able to seek credit from them. The existing credit societies have by the law of II May 1898 been empowered to accept promissory notes secured by land and in this way to make short-terra credit accessible to farmers. Excep- tionally and with the permission of the Minister of Finance they ma}^ give credit not only to their own members, most of whom are tradespeople and small manufacturers, but also to the rural connnunities and the peasants' co-operative societies. Of the 1,179 societies 1,039 published their reports punctually. The other 140, of which some have their spheres in territory now held by the enemy and some have been abandoned, have partialh' discharged their functions but they could not intimate what results they had obtained on i July 1 91 5. (i) See International Review of Agriculture. December 191 4. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The number of members enrolled by these societies amounted to 566, 182. The societies in the principal towns had of course the largest member- ship : in the First Society of Petrograd there were 8,137 members, in the society of the district zemstvo of Petrograd 5,824, in the Society of Trades- men of Moscow 3,390, in the First Society of Odessa 5,477 and in the First Society of Riga 3,576. The smallest membership — thirty-six — was shown by the society of Golodaev in the Don district. The societies and their membership were distributed as follows in the different territories : Name of Region 1. Northern 2. Moscow manufacturers 3. Central farmers 4. On and beyond the Volga .... 5. White Russia and Ivithuania . . . 6. Little and »South Western Russia . 7. Region of Southern Steppes . . . 8. Kankasas g. Siberia 10. Central Asia 11. Baltic Provinces 12. Kini^dom of Poland Total . . . 1,039 566,182 As can be seen the majority of existing credit societies, and those hav- ing the largest membership, are scattered over Little Russia and the south and south western part of the State, that is over the districts which are noted as providing corn to Europe — the governments of Poltova, Tcher- nigoff, Kiev, Bessarabia, Tauria and PodoUa. The capital of the societies amounted to 144,268,000 roubles 115,791,000 roubles constituting the working capital, 15,579,000 roubles the reserve funds, and 12,898,000 roubles special capital. The capital of the First Petrograd Credit Society was 4,644,000 roubles, that of the Second Petrograd vSociety 4,327,000 roubles, and that of the Moscow Tradesmen 5,259,000 roubles. Their deposits reached 586,738,000 roubles, 188,615,000 roubles being withdrawable after notice had been given, and 398,123,000 — which was on current account — without notice. Their loans amounted to 106,318,000 roubles. Discount being the chief business of the existing credit societies, 493,727,000 roubles under the head of exchange was more than half the whole sum on the credit side of their accounts. They lent 115,960,000 Number of Societies Membership n 52,662 27 13.541 43 17.794 65 33.720 79 26,563 244 140.033 248 162,862 136 63,998 30 12,805 18 5.883 49 26,395 23 9,926 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 3 1 roubles on paper securities ; 35,526,000 roubles on merchandise and certi- ficates of merchandise ; and 71,015,000 roubles on real estate, of which 5,575,000 roubles was lent on promissory notes secured by land. The value of the paper securities was entered in the books as 23,918,000 roubles. These few leading facts are enough briefly to indicate the position and the activity of the existing credit societies on I July 1915. Their signifi- cance, as regards their methods and the operations they conduct, is for the most part local. UNITED STATES. THE CO-OPERATIVE MARKETING OF I,IVE STOCK IN WISCONSIN. —R. M. Orchard in The Banker-Farmer, Vol. Ill, No. 7, June 1916. Champaign (Illinois). Farmers' associations for the marketing of live stock in the United States now number about 500 and have had some excellent results. The Muscoda Farmers' " Shipping " Association may be taken to be typical of organizations of this kind in Wisconsin. Its members are a group of farmers who have agreed among themselves to market their live stock together. In November 1913 they came together and chose a president, a secretary-treasurer or manager, and a yard man. A farmer desiring to sell by the medium of the association gives a list of his stock to the manager, who keeps a register of the names of as- sociated farmers, the number and kind of animals they have to market, and the approximate weights of these. When the manager sees from his register that he has a truckload of hogs, cattle or sheep ready to be marketed he engages a truck from the railway company by telephone for a particular day : and then, also by telephone, instructs the farmers to deliver their stock in time. On the appointed day it is received, weighed and marked by the yard man, who keeps a list of it and of the owners, weights and marks. The animals are then loaded and sent to Chicago or Milwaukee, according to their number and quality. On the same day the manager sends to the com- mission house, which will dispose of the stock in the central market, an in- voice in which the names of the owners and the weights and marks of the animals are indicated. When the truck reaches the central market it is unloaded and the animals are fed and watered. If they are cattle they are then sorted according to their owners ; if they are hogs it is considered more profitable to grade them according to quality. The animals are afterwards weighed and sold ; and the commission agent to whom they have been con- signed pays, on the very day of the sale, the money due for them into the account which the " Shipping " Association has at a bank. He afterwards makes a report of the sale to the manager of the association, stating the costs of freight, yard accommodation, insurance and food, as well as the arnount of the commission, all of which have been deducted from the gross price. 32 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION On receiving this statement the manager in his turn draws up a report set- ting forth the weight of the animals before their journej^ and at the central market, the price obtained at the central market for all the stock and for that of individual owners, the individual's share of expenses on the journey and at the market., the commission charged b\' the association and the share of this falling on individuals. He then prepares a statement and draws a cheque for each individual owner. The charge for feeding the animals on their journey is based on the num- ber loaded in a truck and the amount of food given them. For hogs the usual charge is from five to eight cents a head. The commission charged by the association to cover expenses and form a small reserve fund is three per cent, on the price of cattle and hogs and 15 cents a head on calves. A farmer not a member of the association may market his stock by its means if he pay a commission of 5 per cent, on the price of cattle and hogs and 25 cents a head on calves. The sums thus received pay the manager's salary a:id the wages of the yard man and his helpers and cover any losses incurred by the death or depreciation of animals during their journe^^ Thus it may be said that by exacting from the owners a small premium the association insures the live stock against the risks of transport. In 1915 the association sent out 56 truckloads of stock, as against 43 in the previous 3^ear ; and 155 farmers availed themselves of its services. Precise figures cannot be given as to the amount of extra profit which the farmers derive from such co-operative marketing but it may be estimated approximately at from 5 to 25 per cent. This extra profit might however become a loss if the manager did not watch the market very closely. Part 11: Insurance and Thrift GERMANY. THE PRINCIPAL FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES FOR THE INSURANCE OF CATTLE IN EAST PRItSSIA. SOURCES : Maktens, Administrator : Vom Hauptverbande Ostpreussischei Viehversichemngs-vereinc. Berichte fiir 1914 und 1915 {The Principal Federation of East Prussian Societies for the In- surance of Cattle : Reports for 1914 and 1915). Georgine, nos. 65-66, 69-70 and 77-78 of 14 and 28 August and 25 September 191 5 and nos. 39-40 and 41-42 of 13 and 20 Ma^' 1916, Koenigsberg. § I, General report of activity in 1914 and 1915. The federation was definitely founded on 11 November 1913 by the union of sixteen societies, and after having freed itself from the guardian- ship of the Chamber of Agriculture it reached the important position of an independent enterprise, deriving profits from its reinsurance fund and the subsidies allotted to it by the Chamber of Agriculture and the province, in the form of sums assigned to administrative ends. It was obliged at the beginning of the war to limit to the transaction of current business its federal activity but this could resume its former course from 15 December 1914. In the first year of its existence the federation did no more than extend insurance within the territory of the province, prii.- cipally by founding new societies in favour of which it pursued an energetic propaganda. But since the war continued, the following year — 1915 — could not but be devoted to an effort to maintain the status quo and to re- conquer lost ground. This was why the federation was obliged to confine 34 GERMANY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT itself to seconding, by its actions and b}^ support in the form of advice, the federated societies and to reinforcing their interior organization . The res- toration of societies which had not been able to survive the crisis had also to be secured. Already small proprietors were represented as well as agricultural la- bourers, the betterment of whose peculiar economic conditions is one of the first tasks of local societies for the insurance of cattle. The large landowners tended to form societies among their employees and cause the small local agriculturists to adhere to these. They adhered to them themselves because they wished to encourage their development ; they assumed the duties necessary to their conduct and showed their in- terest in them on ever}- occasion. The need for insuring the cattle of the employees of large estates, and the profit the employer derived from such insurance, were increasingly recognized. The principal efforts of the federation were towards generalizing its own scope. But among the old societies of the province more difficulty was encountered thrm in districts where societies were freshly founded : the old societies very generally looked upon the federation as an enterprise having a compulsor}^ character and enclosing the seeds of a greater or less restriction of liberty. A meeting of insurance societies had the effect of dissipating these prejudices ; and made clear the principles on which were based the terms of affiliation and the consequence of the measures which facilitated the decision to affiliate. Since the Minister of Agriculture attached particular importance to the insurance of pigs, the federation undertook encpturies into the scope such insurance would have and the question of whether or not it would supply a need. If the federation should extend its activity to this branch of insur- ance it propo.ses to keep its risks entirely separate, that is to differentiate cattle and pig insurance because the latter is attended with very serious risks, especially in East Prussia. Consequenth^ a part of the reserve fund — 10,000 marks (i) — has alreadj'^ been earmarked for pig insurance. In spite of its comparatively small number of members the federation believed itself able to do without larger guarantees, and therefore rejected for the time a scheme cherished by the province of Brandenburg of group- ing provinces in one vast Reinsurance Federation. This scheme embraced East Prussia and Silesia in addition to Brandenburg. The federation's technique of insurance has been tested in the past years. It tends to secure within the federation equal losses or compensa- tion for losses, the favourable condicions with regard to losses which ob- tain in some societies compensating for such as are less favourable in others. If losses indirectly due to the war be left out of account — although the period which has passed may be considered normal as regards casualties among the live stock — it maj'^ be concluded that succeeding years will see this S3^stem of compensation realized, even if important casualties should (i) I mark =^ about 11 ^/^ d at par. PRUSSIAN FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES FOR THE INSURANCE OF CATTI.E 35 occur, and that after the first period of insurance — that is at the end of five 3^ears — the system will have been entirely tested. Having completely covered its costs of foundation the federation could keep its reinsurance fund of 64,616.99 marks intact ; and was thus able to participate to the extent of 40,000 marks in the fourth war loan. § 2. Statistical data as to business done in 1914 and 1915. The following figures resume the statistics for twent3-eight and thirty- one cattle insurance societies, on 31 December 1914 and 31 December 1915 ■ 1914 1915 Number of members , i,oog 931 Number of insured animals 1,202 1,082 Insured sum : a) total sum marks 393,064 369,649 b) average for one animal " 327 342 Premiums: a) total sum: " 6,384.61 7,018.05 b) percentage of insured sum " 2 % 2 % Casualties : a) indemnities: total number " 32 relatively to number of insuied animals " 32.66 % b) slaughtered animals : " 25 c) indemnities in terms of percentage . . 80 % d) gross indemnities " 8,152.50 e) profits from slaughtered animals : total sum " 2,223.75 percentage of insured sum " ' 24.72 /) net indemnities " 5,958.75 Costs of veterinary attendance : " 1.57 % a) total costs: " 700.78 b) percentage of insured sum: " 0.18 % Costs of Administration: a) total sum : " 189.69 6) percentage of insured sum " 0.05 % 39 33- 60 % zo 80 % 9 ,686. 90 3 .265. .85 33. .04 6 ,421, 05 I. .74 % 569. 50 0. .10 % 88.83 0, .02 % 36 GERMANY - IXSURANCE AND THRIFT 1914 1915 Sum held : a) total sum : " 3,145.43 h) percentage of insured sum " o.So % Deficit : a) total sum: " 3,185.19 b) share of federation (* 5) : " 2,548.10 c) shave of societies " 637.09 Causes of casualties : a) accidents: 5 = 16 % b) parturition : 7=22% c) piilmonarv affections ■ — — Tuberculosis: 5 = 10 % ' d) consequent on aphthous fever .... 3 = 9 % e) affections of the circulation : .... 2 = 6 °/o /) meteorization 2=6% - — Foreign bodies: — — 1= 2.56 % Affections of the stomach and intestines . . ■ — — 9 = 23.08 % g) other internal diseases : 7= 22% 9= 23.08 % h) other external diseases: — — — — i) unknown causes i = 3 % — — 3,517-41 0.0= °o 2,31017 1,855-37 463.80 6 = 15.38 % 4 = 10.26 % 3 = 7-69 % 3 = 7.69 % 2 = 5.13 % 2 = 5-13 % Total niimber of dead animals . . 32 = 100 % ^9 Scope ; On 31 December 1914 the federation comprised thirty-four societies, of which twenty-eight were active, had 1,009 members and insured 1,202 cattle for a total sum of 393,064 marks. Of these twenty-eight societies onh' five were of old foundation and had adhered to the federation ; twenty-three had been founded by it. The war prevented six societies — having 105 members, 148 cattle to insure and an insured sum of 48,000 marks — from becoming active. On 31 December 1915 the federation comprised thirty-five societies of which twenty-six were active, among them the three new societies of Althof-Insterburg, Deubben and Geierswalde. Of the other societies two, those of .Siesiack and Monczen, resumed on I January 1916 the activity which the}' had been obliged to interrupt in consequence of the war ; and three societies, also obliged to suspend business — those of Gerkichnen, Prostken and Kakowen — , as well as two new soci- eties — of Augustponen and Enzuhnen — , will probably have had part in the PRUSSIAN FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES FOR THE INSURANCE OF CATTLE 37 operations of 1916. Two other societies were founded at the end of 1915 {Bledan and Schwanis) and these also became active on i January. The twenty-six active societies comprise altogether 931 members and 1,082 heads of cattle insured for 369,649 marks. These figures show retrogress- ion in comparison with those for the previous 5"ear (1914) ; but it is right to note the difference in this respect between the movement of business within the societies during the year, and the total cessation of the activity of societies fnlh^ active in the previous year. In the case of the former the reduction in the number of members was one of only tliirty-one, that of ani- mals was of forty-five and that of the insured sum 4,875 marks. As of these fortj'-five heads of cattle indemnities were paid for thirty-nine the re- trogression should be expressed as one only of six. In the second case, in which we include societies not yet active and those which had ceased to be so since the preceding year, the retrogression is certainly very marked, the reduction being one of 150 members, 211 heads of cattle and 33,400 marks. The difference between the number of members and of heads of cattle shows that it is not only owners of single cows— for whom tliis organization was especially intended - who have adhered to the various societies. The statistics allov/the further conclusion that small societies, insuring only twelve, fifteen or eighteen heads of cattle, have been founded. The princi- ple of admitting small societies, on wliich the federation rests, has entirely withstood proof. The federation has adopted an important principle — that namely which obliges members to insure with their societies all the cattle they possess on the land within the society's sphere, of course in the measure in which the animals allow of insurance. Although this rule is not always easy to apply, and is often an obstacle to the foundation of new societies and espe- cially to the adherence of existing societies insuring cattle, the federatioti judges it necessary not to depart from it because only its unerring and in- flexible observation can ensure to the small landowners all the advantage which insurance is capable of affording them.. Insu'/ed Value : The total sum insured was 393,064 marks in 1914, that is 327 marks per insured animal which gives a reasonable standard. The same may be said of 1 91 5 when this average was 342 marks It is however to be antici- pated that it will be much raised owing to the increase in the price of cattle. We here touch on a question as to which it is not always easy to give weight to the federation's principle in the model by-laws of the societies On the one hand live stock must not be insured above its value lest too great risks be assumed ; on the other it must not be insured below its value if it be desired to give to the insurer real help which will allow him, if a casualty occur, to procure an animal to take the place of that lost. The case of undei-insurance is met with most frequently : people tend to insure their beasts below their value because they are unwilling to pa}- a premium ^8 GERMANY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT which seems to them excessive before the}' arc face to face with the dreaded occurrence of a casualty. It is this state of mind which it is attempted to combat. The federation makes a point of the insurance of cattle up to their full value, even when this has been increased, because only thus can the eco- nomic aim be fully realized. Premiums : Two per cent, has generally been exacted during the first period of insurance. This rate has been universally applied to newly founded societies, but in the case of old societies already' adherent to the federation it has been possible from the beginning to charge a lower rate. It is probable that after the first period and at the end of each succeed- ing one the level of premiums will be quite different in the different soci- eties : it varies according to the measure in which the societies have had to bring the federation under contribution during the past period of insurance. The societies which, thanks to good farming, have gone onh' a very little beyond that normal rate of casualties for which the federation compensates to the extent of four fifths, or have had no casualties at aU to register, can count on a reduction of the premium bringing it below two per cent. On the other hand those which have not been able to make up for the various 3'ears during which the}- went be3'ond the normal rate, by economies in other years during which the}'' did not reach it, must face the prospect of increased premiums in the succeeding period of insurance Casualties ; In 1915 indemnities were paid for thirt^'-nine animals, that is 3.60 per cent, of the total number insured, as against thirty- two or 2.66 per cent, in 1914. Of these thirty-nine animals twenty were slaughtered. The gross sum of the indemnities was 9,686.90 marks or 80 per cent, of the insured value. The sum realized for the slaughtered animals was 3,265.85 marks or 33.04 per cent, of the gross amount of indemnities, the net amovint of these being therefore only 6,421.05 marks or 1.74 per cent, of the total value insured. In this connection it should be stated that the percentage of the gross sum of indemnities realized from the slaughtered animals was much higher than in the preceding year — 33.04 as against 24.72 per cent. It is suscep- tible however of a yet greater rise in value. Experience shows generally that during a quinquennial period an insurance societ}' has one or two good years in which it does not even reach the normal level of casualities, two medium years in which it receives only a little more than the sum which it has to pay out in indemnities, and one or two bad A^ears in which indemnities much surpass the amount of premiums. The differences in the proportion of the profit from enforced slaugh- PRUSSIAN FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES FOR THE INSURANCE OF CATTLE 3q- tering to the total sum of indemnities are sometimes so great that they cannot be explained only by the varying quality of the meat sold: they are due to the diversity of the causes leading to the animal's death but they give rise to a certain doubt as to the skill with which some societies conduct commercial transactions. It is true that some districts have still to submit to the knacker's exclusive right to the carcase for which, as a rule, he pays a very small indemnity or none at all. The federation however does all it can to stimulate the societies to obtain the maximum profits from slaughtered animals, in order thus to reduce total losses to the strict minimum. Costs of Veterinary Attendance : These amounted in 1915 to 569.50 marks or o.io per cent, of the round sum insured. In comparison with 1914, in which 700.78 marks or 0.18 per cent, was spent under this head, they had certainly diminished ; but tliis should not lead to the conclusion that most veterinary surgeons in discharging their duties observed the precepts of general interest which are at the basis of the activit}' of the insurance societies. The diminution is to be ascribed to the fact that veterinary surgeons were summoned less frequently, for the good reason that they were not to be found evers'where where the}' were wanted. Conditions resultant on the war — the generally inferior quality of live stock — j^roduced a conviction that in regard to the question of risks the introduction of a compulsory veterinary examination is absolutely necessary. Unfortunate!}' this measure would in many cases be a dead letter, for in numerous if not in all districts no veterinary' surgeon is available, so that insurance which provided for the compulsory examination would be im- practicable. Where a veterinar}' surgeon is to be had his services would involve the societies in a large additional expense. It was necessary there- fore to give up the project of making the compulsory examination general,, merely exhorting the societies to exercise the greatest caution when there was question of their accepting new animals for insurance. Costs of Administration : Like the costs of veterinary attendance those of administration form a part of the expenses which, if losses keep within their normal limit of 70 per cent., ought to be covered by receipts; and they should naturally, in the interest of the societies, be kept as low as possible. Their total sum — 88.83 iiiarks or 0.02 per cent, of the w'hole insured value — shows a decrease as compared with 1914 when such percentage was 0.05. This item of the societies' expenditure will in the future be perceptibly increased: for hith- erto the societies have not had to send representatives to large meetings, pa3'ing their travelling expenses ; and they will have gradually to increase their stock of printed matter, with which the federation initialh' provided 40 GERMANY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT them, free of cost. The condition necessary to keeping administrative costs as low as possible is that of gratuitous servdce. The society has been preserved in a good condition financially because the A-ear 1915 allowed the principle of compensatory losses — which, as we have seen, is fundamental to the federation — again to be observed. This result is due, it is true, to the grant of a sum of looo marks by the ' ' Notstands- fonds " of East Prussia, as indemnit}^ for losses indirectly caused b}' the war, and to the effect of the subsidies accorded b}" the Minister of Agricul- ture in aid of the societies in embarrassed circumstances. For this object the federation receives an annual grant of 3,000 marks. But dur- ing these two years the whole of this amount has not been used, and it has been possible to pa^^ the sum so saved into a relief fund, which is intend- ed to allow aid to be given at the end of the period of insurance to soci- eties then in the debt of the federation for advances. In this way these so- cieties will not have to raise their premiums paj'able in the succeeding pe- riod in order to redeem the debts thus incurred. A request made to the minister for fixed financial support, which would allow costs of administra- tion and former printing costs to be met, was however not granted. Causes of Casualties : In this respect 1915 showed improvement as compared with 1914. The societies can have no influence except as regards casualties caused b}^ accidents , difficult parturition and the swallowing of foreign bodies. The accidents have certainly increased in number by one; but the casualties consequent on parturition have diminished by three, those consequent on tuberculosis by two and those consequent on aphthous fever bj" one. By putting into execution its plan of adopting the method recognized by the State, as being the best for the fight against tuberculosis and that which those interested can themselves follow, the federation v/ill reduce the ill effects of this devastating disease on the total sum of losses. But this plan cannot be put into execution before the return of normal circumstancs. The federation can also exercise a certain influence in favour of the re- duction of casualties consequent on accidents and it will not fail to do so. The accidents are usually due to the carelessness if not to another fault of the insurer. The federation devotes much attention to a revision, as comiplete and extensive as possible, of all the rules concerning its rigorous inspection of the care given to animals and of the manner in which they are lodged and fed. Diseases of the digestive organs (intestinal tumours, appendicitis, twisted intestines, obstructions, digestive troubles) were responsible for nine casualtis in 1915 — a very large number, perhaps explained by the bad quality of the forage har\^est. Among other internal diseases occur cardiac affections, dropsy, affections of the matrix, inflammation of the spinal cord, fistulae of the salivary glands, and blood poisoning. PRUSSIAN FEDERATION OF SOCIETIES FOR THE INSURANCE OF CATTEE 4I Financial Position. Number of Casualties beyond the Normal Limit, Compensation for Risks {the "fifth") : The total expenditure of the societies under the head of casualties, costs of veterinar}- attendance and costs of administration — premiums paid to the federation being included —, amounted — when the receipts from premiums paid to the societies, the slaughtering of animals and the minis- terial subsidies left over for 1915 had been deducted — to a sum of 2,319.17 marks (3,185.18 marks in 1914); and in this outlay the federation participated to the extent of four fifths or 1,855.37 marks (2,548.10 in 1914), and the societies to that of one fifth or 463.80 marks (637.09 in 1914). The federa- tion has not yet had to exercise its right, conferred on it by the by-laws, to make societies, which have had to pay extraordinarily high indemnities owing to bad farming, participate in payment for the excessive casualties to the extent of two fifths. The total stun advanced by the federation to the societies during the five 3-ears for which the period of insurance lasts is covered by the soci- eties' reserves. If they have no reserves — that is if a'^ry year their number of casufilties be above the normal — , or if their reserves be insufiicient — that is if their bad years have been more frequent than their good — , they are not bound to make special payments to cover the federation's advances. They have recourse to an expedient less felt by their members, namelj'' they increase the premiums for the next period of insurance. The amount which a society pays to the federation is thus augmented, and little by little the debt contracted with the federation is redeemed by payments spread over five years and not by a single payment. The proportion in which the premium is increased varies naturally with the size of the debt. In view of the ministerial aid given to the less wealthy societies, which have had to sufier particularly bad years through no fault of their own, this debt should never reach an exorbitant level, and there should be question only of a fraction added to the percentage payable as premium and of the payment of pfennigs (i) by the insurers. There are federations of which some societies have been able to reduce to 0.85 per cent, the rate of their premiums which was at first 2 percent. The respon- sibility of societies for casualties surpassing the normal limit shows that they are no longer interested in the economical management of common funds. Precaution is justified ; for if the federation placed itself in a position to pay for all casualties surpassing the normal Hmit the societies might easily adopt such methods of administration that prudence and thrift would be the least of their cares. The largest reserve fund would be unable to hold out for long. To compensate for risks with the premiums of the various societies and within the federation is to give to the technique of insurance its one and only firm basis. It may be noted in this connection that the ex- cess of casualties over the normal limit is influenced, in the societies and con- (i) I pfeimig := ,01 mark. 4 42 GERMANY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT sequently in the federation, by the fact that ministerial aid is given to so- cieties having to face financial difficulties. : The total sum held by the societies was 3,5i7.4i"marks in igis/that is 0.95 per cent, of the insured value, and shows progress as compared with 1914 when it was 3,145.43 marks and 0.80 per cent, of the insured 'value. Only four societies are in debt to the federation and they are so to no impor- tant extent. All the others have reserve funds : some very small — 6.33 marks, other as much as 334.86 marks. It should be mentioned that, contrary to its first intention of calling in advances only at the end of the period of insurance, the federation has decided, in order to avoid the conse(]uent loso of interest, to ask the societies for repayment in future as soon as better times have brought them excess profits and made it possible for them to think of a repayment, however gra- dual, of their debts. ITALY. THE MUTUAIv FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICUIyTURE. SOURCES : Ferrari (Prof. Prospero) ly'assiciirazione contro gli infortuni sul lavoro in agricoltura (In- surance against the accidents of agricultural labour), Rome, 1914. Atti del Congresso per le Mutue infortuni sul lavoro, con statuti e istruzioni per la costituzione di'casse mutue infortuni sul lavoro (Proceedings of the Congress of the Mu- tual Societies for the Accidents of lyabour, with statutes and instructions for the consti- tution ot mutual funds for the accidents of labour). Milan, 19 February 1911. National Committee of Agrarian Mutualitj'. Milan, Arti Grafiche, 1911. Statutes and Reports of the various Mutual Funds in Italy. A recent vote of the general council of the Istituto nazionale per la muttwlita agraria, that the government might present to the chamber as soon as possible the scheme for a law vi^hich vi^ould extend compulsory insurance against the accidents of labour to fieldworkers (i), has revived in Italy the discussion of this important problem which for long years (i) See in this connection, La Mutualitd Agraria, the organ of the Istituto Nazionale per la Mutualitd, Agraria, Rome, no. 21, 30 Septembei IQ16. Recentli' the General I,abour Confe- rence resolved as follows : " The directing council of the General I.. 1073, i October 1916. (2) Association of Vercellese Agriculturists. iQog • •• . liras 8,442.52 1910 . . » 25,433.26 1911 . . » 28,073.05 1912 . . » 42,568.70 1913 . . . » 58,628.15 MUTUAI, FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICULTURE 45 employed, in the measure fixed by the law for compulsory insurance (31 Januarj^ 1904, no. 51) now in force, namely : i) in the case of death an indemnity equal to five years' wages ; 2) in the case of total permanent disablement an indemnit}^ equal to six 3^ears' wages and never less than 3,000 liras (i) ; 3) in the case of partial permament disablement an indemnity equal to six times the amount by which the yearly wages have been or may be reduced, and never less than 500 liras. Up to 1909 indemnification for temporary disablement was excluded. It was then admitted and extended to cover workmen not compelled by law to insure, and under this head about 2,600 liras was paid in 1913 in indemnities for 1,350 working days. The sum of 239,412.05 liras was paid in ten years for various accidents as follows : 1904 liras 2,855.00 1905 » 10,248.00 1906 » 15,568.35 1907 » 23,855.12 1908 » 17,839.90 Premiums are fixed according to the area of the land and the cultivated land, and — reimbursements being taken into account — they have varied from 0.52 liras to 0.62 liras a hectare (2). The chief merit of the Mutual Fund of Vercelli, apart from that at- taching to the position of pioneer, is that it has based insurance not only on the value of the wages of each single labourer, but also on the sum of the labour required bj' a determined area according to the mode of its cul- ture. Consequently a premium attaches to an area independently of any identification of particular labourers ; and therefore the pay-books and the registration of labourers, on which the institutions insuring industrial work- ers insist, have been abolished. When the amount of labour required for a crop has been determined as well as the area it occupies within a farm, the particular system of rota- tion of crops being taken into account, average sums for a hectare can be computed. In Vercelli and adjacent lands these have been fixed at 157 liras and 175 liras a hectare. At the rate of 5 per cent, they give the amounts of the initial preventive premiums as 0.785 lira and 0.875 lira a hectare, which amounts have been reduced to 0.52 lira and 0.62 lira by the effect of reim- bursements. The financial year of the fund begins on ii November and ends on 10 November, thus corresponding to the farming year. When the books are (i) IS = 1. 261 1 liras. (2) I hectare = 2 acres i rood 35.383 poles. 46 ITALY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT balanced annually the difference between the receipts (premiums and any other sources of revenue) and the expenditure (payment of indemnities and administrative and other expenses) is, as to three tenths, assigned to a reserve fund, and is restored, as to seven tenths, to the members of the society proportionately to the premiums they have respectively paid. If there be a deficit the members are asked for a supplementary^ premium proportionate to that they have already paid. There may be no trespas- sing upon the reserve fund until it has attained to the sum of the premiums in the first year of the society's activity. At first the fund's activity reached only the arrondissement of Vercelli ; then it was extended to the arrondissement of Novara and to Ivomellina, and thereafter successively to the arrondissements of Biella, Casale Monfer- rato, Pa via and Abbiategrasso. Only those may belong to it who are directly or indirectly engaged in agriculture, as farmers or agents. For admission a written application is necessary in which the total area of the land under cultivation must be stated. The whole number of the members constitute the society's general meeting. The society is administered by a directing council composed of a president and six members, elected by the general meeting by secret ballot and a majority of votes. The president holds office for three years and is always eligible for re-election. The other members of the council also hold office for three years : one third of them are elected every year and they are not eligible for re-election for a year after they have ceased to hold office. The general meeting also elects six arbiters, of whom three determine wages according to declared area and three pay indemnities. The arbiters hold office for three years, a third of them are elected every year, and they are always eligible for re-election. The meeting also elects an- nually from among the members three legal representatives and two depu- ties for these. All offices are unpaid, but the arbiters have the right to be reimbursed for expenses incurred in the course of their duties. § 2. The mutual fund of Florence. The mutual fund of the rural proprietors of Tuscany for the insurance of persons employed on farms against the accidents of labour (i), wliich has its offices at Florence, was constituted on the initiative of the local agrarian committee by a resolulution of 4 December 1908 and received the status of a " moral body " by a royal decree of 25 February 1909. It began its activity on 5 April 1909, including within its scope all Tuscany, that is to say the provinces of Florence, Arezzo, Sienna, Lucca, Pisa, Livorno and Grosseto. The fund completed on 29 February 1916 its seventh year, and it appears from its last pubhshed report that at that date, which term- {1) Cassumutuadei proprietaridi fondirustici in Toscana per I'assicutazione del personate dellc aziende agrarie contro gli infortuni sul lavoto. MUTUAI, FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICULTURE 47 inated its year of business, it had 768 enrolled .members, and insured g6i farms which comprised 12,634 pieces of land having a total area of 318,607 hectares. The distribution according to the kinds of cultivation was as follows : Sowed land, vines, olives hectares 86,404 Sowed land only " 53,650 Vines and special crops " 2,464 Underwood " 94,452 Forest trees " 30,261 Fallow, pasture " 51,376 This fund insures all persons, whether compelled to insure or not, who are employed* in any kind of agricultural labour, permamently or casually ; and since almost everywhere lands are held on the metayage system, the in- surance comes to comprise not only all the members of the cultivators' fa- milies but also all the casual labourers, the hraccianti, and the labourers employed on building, forestry, threshing etc : The total number of these persons was computed on 28 February 1915 to be 119,938 cultivators, of whom 44, 455 were males over thirteen, 34,931 adult women, 32,192 men and women over sixty-five, and 8,360 boys under thirteen whom the insurance did not cover. There were also about 6,800 casual labourers who were enrolled by the fund. The annual premium is fixed according to the area of the farm, the va- rious types of ctdtivation being taken into account, as well as the relation between the area and the rural population, and special risks attaching to any type of cultivation, to operations for the conversion of products, or to the use of machines etc. The complexity and the variety of agrarian conditions in the different Tuscan provinces has rendered it necessary to establish tariffs or premiums var^ung from 0.30 lira to 1.50 liras a hectare for lands bearing grass crops, and joined to lands on which plants of the tree family are grown ; while fixed premiums of 0.40 lira and 0.20 lira have been adopted in the case of woods and underwoods. Since I914 premiums have been reduced by 20 per cent., the result of previous years allowing svich reduction to be effected without danger to the safety of the Mutual Fund. This fund has further provided for the constitution of a reserve formed from admission fees of o.io lira for each hectare of cultivated land and of 0.05 lira for each hectare of woodland and pasture, and from the interest on the sums on deposit. At the end of the seventh year of the Mutual Fund, that is on 29 February 1916, such reserve amounted to 124,035.44 liras, and this when joined to a special reserve of 10,000 liras gives a sum of 134,035.44 liras. The Mutual Fund of Florence indemnifies, in cases of death and total or partial permanent disablement, anyone incurring such in the course of 4^ ITALY - IXSURAXCE AXD THRIFT labour (i), whether or not he be compelled to insure. It also paj's indem- nities to persons temporarily disabled in the course of labour, but only if they be subject to the obligation to insure. However in the case of grave accidents, happening to labourers who are not compelled to insure and en- tailing expenses for hospital or other medical treatment and prolonged temporary disablement, the fund grants fitting subsidies. These indemnities are payable to the victims of accidents arising in the course of labour who are not subject to the obligation to insure. To those within the scope of the law of 31 Januars' 1904, no. 51, as to acci- dents of labour, indemnities are paid at the rate of six times the amount of annual wages for permanent total disablement, and five times their amount for death. From T909 to 1915 indemnities paid in response to the claims which were met amounted to 361,438.17 liras, namely : Year 1909 I9IO I9II I9I2 1913 I9I4 I9I5 Claims Met. Indemnities Paid. Liras. 92 9.99546 220 25.36373 328 49,850.49 410 62,740.10 513 81,722.81 547 97,978.78 3I8 33,786.80 Total . . . 2,428 361,438.17 The classification of the causes of the accidents has a certain value because statistics of this description are almost entirely lacking. The data as to the Mutual Fund of Florence, which we here reproduce, explain its activity in a district of very complex agriculture and have therefore a particular importance. The kinds of labour in the course of which acci- dents were incurred were as follows : (1) If a member meet with an accident he must notify the fact on a special form, on the back of which the doctor must give the necessary facts as to the nature of the injurj' and its consequences and the term of disablement. In the case of every accident the member is oblig- ed to bear the cost of the first medical certificate and attendance. \\TieE the doctor's certifi- cate testifies that the victim has been permanently disabled the Mutual Fund invites him to receive a visit from .he fund's skilled doctors, who together investigate and estimate the de- gree of partial disablement , the corresponding deduction in labour [lower, and the indemnity due. MUTUAI, FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICULTURE 49 Accidents distributed according to the labour which caused them. Woodcutting Falls from carts, transport. Falls from trees, pruning . Building Work in cellars Work of herds Cutting forage Falls in general. Tilling =oil, bringing it under cultivation Harvest and hay harvest Various agricultural labour. Threshing Quarries, claypits. . . . . Presses, mills Carpenter's work Supervision and keeper's work Various causes Total . . . I I II III 1909-10 I 1910-11 1911-12 43 23 17 16 14 13 II 10 190 III 41 24 53 12 22 16 25 18 44 23 20 6 4 6 6 12 443 162 60 56 73 16 26 26 51 58 48 18 17 4 2 24 659 IV 1912-13 166 86 68 73 35 59 30 37 38 69 28 44 14 9 9 788 V I9I3-I4 VI 1914-15 170 89 85 77 52 73 40 78 53 58 75 40 22 6 14 6 20 958 223 88 99 80 59 76 46 100 78 63 112 40 15 18 13 30 I148 VII I9I5-I6 202 80 94 63 15 51 39 90 53 74 60 20 15 12 16 9 26 Total 919 1077 467 443 435 203 320 208 391 308 364 321 186 79 60 69 38 136 5105 From this complexity of facts the rich economic and social results to which the Mutual Fund of Florence has attained can easily be understood, results which have had the great merit of introducing Tuscan agriculturists to the principle of mutuality, and of stimulating the metayer's activity by interesting him and by binding him more closely to the soil which he tills. § 3. The mutuaIv fund of milan. The lyombard Mutual Fund for Insurance against the Accidents of Agricultural I^abour (i) was founded on the initiative of the local association of proprietors and managers of properties. It sby-laws date from 21 May 1910 and it began its activity in November of the same year. (i) Cassa tniitua lombarda di Assicuraziune conlro gli infoihiyii snl lavoto nell'agricoltuia. 50 ITAIvY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT Its activity extends over the Lombard district which presents a great variety of forms of agriculture. Subsequently to its foundation it fixed its annual premiums, based on area, in accordance with these forms and the respective risks they entail. The insurance covers cases of death and of permanent total disable- ment ; partial disablement is not considered unless it is equal to ten per cent, of total disablement ; indemnities are paid after twenty-one days for temporary total disablement. The indemnities are as follows : in case of death — to a man 2,000 liras, to a woman 1,000 liras, to a child 500 liras ; in case of permament total disa- blement — to a man 2,500 liras, to a woman or child 1,200 liras ; in case of temporary disablement — i lira a day to a man, 0.50 lira a day to a woman or child, the latter being defined as a person between twelve and eighteen years old. At the end of 1914 the fund had 416 members. In this year claims were made for 207 accidents and 183 of them were acknowledged. Of these 176 were met by temporary indemnities which amounted to 3,919 liras; one non-indemnifiable fatal accident caused a grant of 400 liras ; and six claims on account of permament partial disablement were indemnified by a total sum of 1,040 liras. The victims included thirty children, 161 men and sixteen women, their ages being as follows : from 18 to 20 years 17 from 61 to 65 years 7 " 21 to 30 years 38 more than 65 years 7 " 31 to 45 years 49 of indefinite age 13 " 46 to 60 years 46 children from 12 to 14 years 30 The accidents occurred in the months in which work was most intense and in which special works, such as the rearing of silkworms, are usually accomplished. The classification of the causes of accidents is peculiarly important. It results from it, according to the opinion of experts, that the gravest risk in agriculture is not so much one due to the use of machines as a risk in- herent in the very nature of the industry. Thus fifty-six accidents occur- red through falls from carts or haylofts, thirty-seven were attendant on herd- ing animals, twenty-five on transporting products, fourteen on the labours of the hay-harvest and nine on those of forestrj^ while only thirteen out of 207 involved injuries by agricultural machines or implements. The injuries which had such origins affected different parts of the body as follows : feet 51 accidents arms 16 accidents head 8 " face 6 " eyes 3 groin I hands . . . . 46 trunk . . . . 38 legs . . . . . 38 MUTUAI. FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICUI^TURE 5 1 The statistics as to indemnities are as follows : Years 1910-11 1911-12 1912-13 1913-14 For death — — — i " permament disablement — i 5 6 " temporary disablement — 6 57 176 Without indemnity 5 — — 5 Pending decision — — i ig Total 5 7 63 207 If it be taken into account that in four 3^ears 10,623.19 liras was paid and 1,670 liras was put on one side for accidents as to which a decision was pending, it results that an accident implied in general an average cost of 39 liras, to which must be added 3 liras for expenses, giving a total of 42 liras. Finally if we compute the cost of accidents according to their consequences we find that, in addition to expenses, the average cost of temporary disablement was 26.50 liras, of permament disablement 258 hras. § 4. The MUTUAI, FUNDS OF TURIN, BOI.OGNA AND ROME. Following the example of the funds of Vercelli, Florence and Milan, three others, of which we will speak briefly, soon arose. The Piedmontese Mutual Agricultural Insurance (i). — On the initia- tive of the Piedmontese Agricultural Co-operative Syndicate this fund was instituted by a resolution of 20 June 1910 for mutual insurance against the accidents of labour, especially in the provinces of Turin, Alexandria and Cuneo. Its working is like that of the Milanese fund. The Mutual Agrarian Accidents' Society of Bologna (2). — This society was promoted by the Interprovincial Agrarian Federation, was constituted by a resolution of 21 April 1910 and was authorized by a royal decree of II May 1910. Its activity extends especially to the provinces of Bologna, Rovigo, Mantua, Ferrara, Modena, Ravenna and Parma. It follows al- most the same rules as the funds of Vercelli, Florence and Milan. Premiums are paid proportionately to the area of the insured land and in the society's last year of business varied from o.io lira to 0.50 lira the hectare. This figure covers the insurance of labour-ers bound to insure (those employed on threshing machines, on steam forage-presses, on wood-cutting etc.) and that of those not subject to such compulsion. In the case of special works or of factories for the conversion of agri- (!) U Assicurazione Mutua Agricola Piemoniesc. (2) La Mutua Agraria Infortuni di Bologna. 52 ITALY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT cultural products an additional premium is paid, proportionate to the in- crease of the risk. Members who, according to local custom, take their own machines to work on the land of other members need pay no supplementary premium ; but if they thus work on land of which the owner is not a member they must pay a slight supplement. The indemnity paid to labourers who are the victims of accidents varies according to whether or not they be subject to the compulsion to insure. If they be thus compelled, the indemnity is that fixed by the law. If they be not thus compelled the indemnit}^ is fixed as follows : in case of death 2,500 liras ; in case of permament total disablement 3,000 liras ; in case of permament partial disablement a fraction of 3,000 hras propor- tionate to the reduction of working power. Insurance against cases of temporary disablement are not included, but members who apply for it can obtain it by paying an additional pre- mium of 70 per cent. This mutual fund also guarantees its members, in return for a small additional premium, against all liability they may incur by their own acts or those of their dependents, whether towards labourers employed on their farms or in any other case contemplated by the civil code. The Roman Mutual Fund for Insurance against the Accidents of Agri- cultural Labour (i) This fund, which was constituted on the initiative of the Agrarian Committee of Rome by a resolution of i July 1914, extends its activity over the Roman province. It became active in November 19 14, fol- lowing the rules of other mutual funds except in the matter of indemnities which are fixed by the by-laws as f ollws : in cases of death, 2,000 liras for a man and 1,200 liras for a woman ; in cases of total permament disable- ment, 2,500 liras for a man and 1,200 liras for a woman or a child between twelve and eighteen years old. Indemnities are paid for permanent partial disablement only if full working capacity have been reduced by 20 per cent. § 5. The PRIVATE SOCIETIES FOR INSURANCE AGAINST ACCIDENTS. In the preceding paragraphs we have briefly shown the organization of the mutual funds for insurance against the accidents of agriculture which were founded on the initiative of various agricultural associations. It is necessary also to indicate the manner in which the same insurance is effected by private societies, on the system of premiums proportionate to area and collective policies. Assicuratrice Italiana {Italian Insurance Society) . — This society, which has its offices at ]\Iilan, instituted at the end of 1908 insurance pohcies for all the labour of a farm, whether or not works which compelled insurance were practised on it. Premiums are fixed by contract, proportionately (i) La Cassa Mutua Romana di Assicurazione contro gli injortuni sul lavoro neU'agrtculiuta. MUTUAL FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICUI^TURE 53 to the cultivated area and the kinds of cultivation, the basic premium of 2 liras a hectare being capable of reduction when the agriculture is not very intensive. Indemnities are paid in accordance with contracts. They vary from 2,000 liras to 3,000 liras in the case of death, according to the kind of work on which the victim was engaged ; from 2,500 liras to 4,000 liras in the case of permament total disablement; and from 1.50 liras to 2.50 liras a day in the case of temporary total disablement. Among insurance societies this one has the merit of having been the first to deal with the optional insurance of agricultural labours by making premiums proportionate to areas, and thus eliminating the obligation to keep pay-books and registers which is" burdensome to agriculture. Societd anonima italiana di assictirazioni contro gli infortuni {Italian joint Stock Society for Insurance against Accidents, Milan) : — This society in 1905 extended its activity to accidents in the course of agricultural la- bour not subject to the obligation to insure, charging a premium propor- tionate to the cultivated area. It pays in the case of death an indemnity equal to 1500 times the daily wage of the victim up to a maximum of 2,500 liras; in the case of permament total disablement one equal to 1800 times such wage up to a maximum of 3,000 liras ; and in the case of temporary disablement one lira a day. Unione Interprovinciale Agricola {Cremona). — This society began to insure against the accidents of agriculture in 1907, charging 1.50 liras for a hectare of land. This sum was afterwards reduced to 0.75 lira. An in- demnity of 1500 liras is paid in case of death and one of 2,000 liras in case of permament total disablement; wliile in the case of temporary disablement one lira a day is paid to the head of a family and 0.50 lira to its other members for a period limited to six months. La Fondiaria {The Land Society), Florence. — This society, well known for its insurance of life and against hail and fire, undertook in 1910 the collective insurance of agricultural labour, charging premiums varying from 0.90 lira to 2.25 liras according to the risk and the type of policy. The average premium is 1.25 liras a hectare. Indemnities are fixed as follows : in case of death 2,000 liras for a man and 1,000 liras for a woman, in case of permament total disablement 2,500 liras for a man and 1,200 liras for a woman ; in case of permament partial disablement an indemnity proportionate to the reduction in working ca- pacity if this be not of more than 20 per cent. ; in case of temporary disa- blement one lira a day. Insurance to which such premiimis and indemnities attach refers ex- clusively to agriculturists and labourers employed on agriculture, other than those contemplated by the law of 31 January 1904, No. 51, (persons employed on threshing, woodcutting, motor machines) whom it is necess- ary specially to insure with the society. Cassa Nazionale di Assicurazione per gli infortuni degli Operai sul la- voro {National Fund for Insurance against the Accidents occurring to Work- people in the course of Labour), Rome. — This institution, which has a pub- lic character, was formed by the law of 8 July 1883, No. 1473. It is the 54 ITALY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT official agency for insurance against the accidents of labour and industr>% and it was authorized by the royal decree of 14 May 1914, No. 547, to effect, experimentally, insurance against accidents to labourers employed on farm work not contemplated by the law, already cited, of 31 January 1904, No. 51. The insurance implies the premiums and indemnities which we shall mention. Following the example of the mutual funds the National Fund adopted a tariff proportionate to area. The premiums payable on a hectare are fixed according to the kinds of cultivation and are given in the appended table. They vary from 0.75 lira to 3 Hras a hectare in the case of grass crops ; from 1.50 to6Uras a hectare where plants of the tree family are cultivated; from 0.80 lira to 1.60 liras a hectare, without distinction among risks, for rotatory crops; from 1.25 liras to 2.50 liras for woods of forest trees; and from 0.75 lira to 1.50 hras for underwood. These diverse premiums attach to three types of insurance which en- tail maximum, medium and minimum indemnities, as follows : In case of death: Men liras 2,000 Women Children and old people In case of permament total disablement : Men Women ) Children and old people ^ In case of permament partial disablement : Men iNo indemnities No indemnities No indemnities Women . . . . ' of less than of less than of less than Children and old I 5 per cent. 11 per cent. 21 percent. Indemnities Maximum Medium Minimum 2,000 2,000 2,000 1,000 1,000 1,000 500 500 500 2,500 2,500 2,500 1,200 1,200 1,200 people In case of temporary disablement : Men I lira J Women 0.5 » Children and old people — \ if if No disabled disabled indem- for more for more nity. than 5 days than 20 days Relief for 90 days in case of sickness, Men I lira Women 0.50 » Children and old people 0.50 » No No indem- indem- nity. nity. MUTUAIv FUNDS FOR INSURANCE AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRICULTURE 55 Children are taken to include persons between nine and fifteen years old, men and women persons between fifteen and seventy, and old people those over seventy. These indemnities are due only in the case of accidents which occur in the course of agricultural labour or by violent means connected with such labour. All persons within the scope of the existing law as to accidents are excluded from the insurance unless a special contract be made to in- sure them. Sindicato per I'assicurazione mutua degli operai contro gli injortuni sul lavoro fra gli imprenditori di tagli di boschi {Syndicate of ivoodcutting contractors for the mtitiial insurance of ivorkmen against the accidents of labour), Rome. — As is known, the law of 31 January 1904 included woodcutting among the works in the case of which insurance is compulsory, if the la- bourers employed on it numbered more than five. The relevant tariff was however fixed at the somewhat high rate of 90 liras for every thousand liras of wages. The syndicate in question was formed by a resolution of 20 February 1905 and began its activity on 15 March of the same year. Its by-laws rule that it pay indemnities in the measure fixed by the law, that is five times the annual wage in case of death, six times the annual wage in case of permament total disablement, and half his dail}^ wages to a man who is temporarily disabled. Members pay for each labourer they employ a cautionary fee of 10 liras, and a monthly premium equivalent to from 25 to 30 liras for each thousand liras of wages, according to whether the men are employed on making cross-beams or staves or on woodcutting, charcoal burning, etc. MISCELLANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY. THE INSURANCE OF TOBACCO TI^ANTATIONS AGAINST HAII^ IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA. — Wiener Landwirtschaftliche Zeitung (Viennese Agricultural Jour- nal) Vienna, No. 79, 30 September 1916. For many year.s an endeavour has been made to solve the problem of insuring tobacco plantations against hail in Herzegovina, where the tobacco harvest and the vintage may be said to supply the rural population with the whole of their revenue. Since for fiscal reasons the tobacco monopoly could not consider indemniying for damages by paying a higher price for tobacco, some other means of protecting the tobacco planters against the loss caused by such natural causes as hail had to be chosen. At first no scheme of the sort could be realized owing to the conser- vatism of the native producers. Only a comparatively small number of the communes which grew tobacco decided to enter into voluntary con- tracts for insurance against hail. In 1910, therefore, an ordinance compell- ed all the planters of the regie of Bosnia-Herzegovina to insure their to- bacco plantations. The following are the chief provisions of this ordinance : Insurance of tobacco plantations against damage by hail is obligatory for planters of the regie and is based on the principle of mutuaUty. Broadly, the following are the chief features of the S3^stem. When the planters deliver their tobacco to the regie they pay a quota thereof, proportionate to the quantity they deliver, into an insurance fund. The premiums thus have the form of deductions from their normal profits. The sums intended to indemnify them for losses by hail are taken from this insurance fund, the damage sustained being estimated by valuation. The insurance premium is i per cent, of the normal return made by the monopoly for the tobacco, and is paid, as has been said, into the insur- ance fund. If however such premiums do not suffice to compensate for the damage, they may be increased until the}^ are equal to 3 per cent, of the return. The weakening of the insurance fund by the pa^^ment of in- demnities is counterbalanced by loans bearing no interest from the pro- vincial treasury. If when the premium-quota has been raised to 3 per cent, obligations can still not be met — that is if losses cannot be indemnified and loans INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 57 repaid — the amount of losses, as established by the accounts depart- ment, must not be covered fully but onlj^ to the extent of a percentage to be determined b}^ the ratio existing between resources and obligations. If on the other hand the insurance fund reach dimensions which more than allow all obligations to be discharged, the premivmi-quota may be reduced, or obligations may be increased so as to protect the tobacco plantations against damage by wind. An eventual distribution of the tobacco growing communes into zones of more or less risk is contemplated, so that the highest premiums will be paid in the districts most exposed to damage by hail and the lowest in the most favoured and sheltered districts. The technical and administrative documents attaching to this system of insurance are the responsibility of the agencies and offices of the State, and the insurance fund may incur no charge in connection with them. Notice of damage by hail to tobacco plantations must be given within fort^'-eight hours of its occurrence to the competent department ; which must investigate the loss and communicate the results so obtained to the competent official of the regie. Tobacco leaves and fragments of them which have been injured b}' hail must — when they have been collected, treated and dried according to the instructions of the offices of the tabacco regie — be carefully separated from the intact portion of the harvest, and thus delivered, at the same time as the rest of the harvest, to the com- mission of purchase. The damage caused by hail is held to be equivalent to the difference between the actual sum paid for tobacco which has suffered from hail, and the value of the normal intact crop, determined by its estimated qualit}^ and quantity, that is the value of the crop if no hail had fallen on it. The quality and quantity of the crop are estimated by technical officials of the commission of purchase in co-o])eration with a person of trust. If the planter dispute their estimate another is made, a new person of trusc, who is chosen by the president of the commission, taking part in it. In case of a necessity for a third estimate he is chosen by the manage- ment of the tobacco regie. As early as 1910 it was found that the premium-quota of i per cent, was far from adequate to the payment of the estimated losses, and the pro- vincial treasury had to advance a round sum of 100,000 crowns (i) as a loan without interest repa5'able in three annual instalments, to the insurance fund. Consequently in the following year (1911) the premium-quota was raised to 3 per cent, at which level it has remained. The population are beginning to appreciate the advantages of this sys- tem of insurance more and more. It should be regarded as a first attempt to protect the tobacco planter against the elements. Experience will lead to an adaptation of insurance to real needs and to an improvement 4 (i) Austrian crown of gold =10 — d at par. 25 58 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT which will profit the regie as much as the planters. The following are the views on this subjects of the writer of the article : 1. The planter should be made secure of indemnification for all loss occasioned by hail, and not only of a compensation fixed when the tobacco is bought. That is not the time for an estimate by the technical official of the loss occasioned by a fall of hail in July. 2. The valuation af the crop — that is to sa}^ the estimate of the pro- bable crop — is made by the financial insurance departments together with experts chosen from the population, and is revised by officials of the regie. If the fall of hail occur after this estimate has been made the future sale and the quahty of the crop can be computed. There is here an indication as to the manner in which losses should likewise be determined. 3. Although there is much to criticize and to blame in this manner of determining the crop it yet gives the official responsible for computing the damage some opportunity of fixing it near its real figure. But if the fall of hail occur before the estimate has been made the question appears in quite another light. How can the normal crop then be determined ? An estimate can be based only on the trustworthy evidence of the oldest planters, for in some cases the crops on parcels of land are literally rased to the ground. 4. The purchase of the merchandise by the regie and the determin- ation of damages should be effected rapidly, for the work to be done is con- siderable. It is impossible to generalize on this subject, yet it may be said that to use data as to the average yield of a commune incurring damage over a period of five or ten years would give a much firmer and a juster basis of valuation. An average figure of this sort would also be generally profitable to the stabilitj^ of the insurance fund, and would meet a certain sceptism on the part of the planters as to official estimates. The figures as to losses thus obtained would not be subject to variation. GKRIvIANY. I. THE BADEN ASSOCIATIOX FOR INSURANCE AGAINST MORTAI^ITY AMONG lylVE STOCK IN 1915. — Deutsche Schlacht und Viehhof- Zeitung. Berlin, 16 August 1916. At the end of 1915 this association numbered 451 societies and local funds. During the year one fund, formed by fifty-seven members and in- suring 321 heads of live stock, resigned, but the adherence of a new society, having seventy-nine members and insuring 301 heads of live stock, was recorded. In 1915 the insurance covered altogether 168,419 heads of live stock and indemnities were paid in 4,410 cases. lyosses amounted thus to 2.62 per cent, and were higher by 0.15 per cent, than in the preceding year, a fact due to different causes — insufficient care of the animals owing to the absence of owners, scarcity of certain articles of food, impossibility of procuring veterinary attention, spread of aphthous fever. INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 59 The claims for indemnities numbered 4,548, and of them 4,248 or 94.13 per cent, were justified, 129 or 2.84 per cent. (0.16 per cent more than in 1914) were partially so, and 138 or 3.03 per cent (2.18 per cent, less than in the previous year) were unjustified. The total sum of indemnities for which local funds became liable, as a result of claims not or only partially recognized, was 24,431.22 marks (i), of which amount 2,169.16 marks was recovered as the product of the sale of the remains of the animals. Of the 4,410 heads of cattle for which indemnities were paid : 3,745 or 84.92 per cent, were slaughtered for urgent reasons, 430 » 9.75 » » died, 235 » 5-33 » » were slaughtered normally (insurance of live stock raised for butchery by Article 40 4,410 100.00 of the law). The number of cases in which animals were slaughtered for urgent reasons fell by 3.15 per cent, as compared with 1914, that of those which died rose by 2.62 per cent, and that of the insured animals slaughtered normally rose by 0.53 per cent. Animals slain for urgent reasons: A r, , , i. • J.- -L No. of Cases Percent. No. of Cases Percent. After treatment or examination b}'' a _ __ _ _ veterinary surgeon 3,068 81.92 i Without treatment or examination by ^ 3,745 = 89.70 a veternar}^ surgeon • 677 18.08 j Animals which died: After treatment or examination by a veterinary surgeon 118 27 44 j Without treatment or examination by 430 = 10.30 a veterinary surgeon 312 72.46 ) 4,175 = 100.00 The number of animals treated or examined before death by a veterin- ary surgeon was less by 19.30 per cent, than in the previous 3'ear, namely by 8.51 per cent, of cases of slaughter for urgent reasons and by 10.79 P^^ cent, of cases of natural deaths. The following table gives the causes of death or of urgent slaughter in the case of 4,175 insured heads of live stock for which indemnities were paid. (i) I maik = about is at par. 60 INFOR1MA.TION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT Number of Deaths Percentage Order I. Contagious and infectious diseases 692 16.57 3 II. Diseases of the nen-ous system. . 141 3.38 7 III. » )) » respiratory organs 122 2.92 9 IV. » » » digestive « . 1,408 33-72 i V. )> » )) circulation .... 79 1.89 ii VI. » » » urinary organs . . 129 3.09 8 VII. )) » » sexual » . . ']']'] 18.61 2 VIII. » » » locomotive « . , 240 5.75 4 IX. » » )' skin 24 0.58 12 X. Poisoning . . . ". 8 0.19 14 XI. Tumours and constitutional defects 206 4.93 6 XII. Animal parasites 108 2.59 10 XIII. Exterior causes 217 5.20 5 XIV. Undetermined causes 24 0.58 13 4,175 100.00 Cases of indemnities paid for insured an- imals raised for butchery 235 4,410 The most numerous deaths were caused, as in 1914, by diseases of the digestive organs, namely 1,408 or 33.72 of the whole number, which gives an increase of 0.24 per cent. Of these 1,408 deaths 594 were due to diseas- es caused b}- foreign bodies. Deaths due to flatulence among live stock also increased notably, the reason for which must be sought in the fact that in many cases feeding had to be left to inexperienced persons incap- able of correctly regulating the amount of nourishment given to animals. Diseases of the sexual organs occupy the second place as having caused 777 deaths, that is 18.61 per cent, of their total number, or less by 2.47 per cent, than in 1914 when such percentage was 21.08. Contagious and infectious diseases account for 692 deaths or 16.57 P^^ cent, of the whole number, showing an increase of 1.07 per cent, on 1914. Included among, them are : a) Tuberculosis which alone caused 390 deaths. This figure excludes 235 cases of tuberculosis found among animals normally slaughtered. Thus the total number of deaths due to tuberculosis was 625, or 14.17 per cent, of all the deaths. The figure shows an increase of 12.24 per cent, as compared with that of the previous year. INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 6l The increase is due, among other causes, to remissness caused by the war in the superintendence of the inspecting veterinary surgeons, employed by the .State for the campaign against tuberculosis. b) Aphthous fever. The number of deaths caused by this disease have increased from the forty cases reported last year to 124. The increase in the deaths from osteopathyrosis (fragility of bones) is even more pronounced, their number actually surpassing that for 1914 by 100 per cent. The number of indemnities paid in cases of general dropsy has increased, as compared with that of 1914, by 200 per cent. The cause of these diseases is connected with feeding and should be looked for in the insufficient feeding which has resulted on the scarcity of concentrat- ed forage, especially in the case of young animals. 2. INSURANCE AGAINST HAIL IN THE PRINCIPALITY OF HOHENZOLLERN IN 1915-1916. — Mitteihtngen der Centralstelle fur Landwittschaft itnd Gewerbe in Hohenzol- lern. Sigmaringen, 5 April 191 6. The following table shows the development of insurance against hail in the principality of Hohenzollern as a consequence of the preferential contract concluded at Berlin from 15 to 23 May igoo by the Provincial Commission {Landesaiisschuss) with the Mutual Association for Insurance against Hail of North Germany : Administrative Sphere Sigmaringen. . . Hechingen. . . . Gammertingen. . . Haigerloch. . . . Number ' Number Insured Value Premiums Insured Area of Policies of subscribers (in marks) (in marks) (in liectares) (I) 1,369 1405 2,831,642 28,163 5,651 1,003 1.034 955,472 10,478 1,599 471 493 1,047,905 10,671 2,242 268 807 835,458 6,995 1,417 1915 3-III 3-739 5,670,477 56,307 10,909 1914 2,693 3,236 4,437,419 - 9,643 Increase in 1915. . 418 483 1,233,058 — 1,266 As regards the number of claims met and the amount of indemnities, it should be noted that 1915, like the two preceding years, was among the most unfortunate years ever encountered in the principality of Hohenzol- lern. The following are the figures of the balance-sheet which refer to the claims met ; (i) I hectare = 2 acres i rood 35.383 poles. Number of Claims met Number of Pieces Area injured Amount of Land injured by Hail by Hail (in hectares) of Indemnities (in marks) 628 2,985 1,512 160,190 255 897 134 20,511 139 913 324 34.493 39 154 20 3,432 1,061 4.949 1,990 218,626 612 5.700 1,482 206,503 545 4,837 I.514 102,677 62 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT Administrative Sphere Sigmaringen .... Hechingen Gammertingen . . . Hagerloch .... 1915 1914 1913 Thanks to the particularly favourable atmospheric conditions, which have prevailed throughout the greater part of the sphere of activity of the Association for Mutual Insurance against Hail of North Germany, and thanks also to the administrative provisions of some years ago for the form- ation of reserve funds, the association has been able, for the first time in twenty years, to avoid a lev}' of additional premiums. This result is the more satisfactory because the total sum paid in in- demnities is very high. SWITZERLAND. INSURANCE AGAINST HAIIy IN 1915. — Schweizerisches Finanz-Jahrbuch, 1916, 17th year, Beine, Neiimann and Ziinmemiann, 1916. We have already in another issue of this Review dealt with the Swiss Financial Yearbook for 1916, the sixth part of which is given up to insur- ance. Of the different branches of insurance — life, accident, fire and transport insurance and reinsurance — it is insurance against hail which furnishes the facts most interesting to us. This form of insurance, which we have studied in numerous articles in this Review (i), has its place in this yearbook. As is already known insurance against hail is afforded in Switzerland by two mutual aid societies : the Schweizerische H agel-Versicherungsge- sellschaft of Zurich and the Paragrele of Neuchatel. The former of these extends its activities over the whole territory of the Confederation and in- sures all agricidtural products against the risks of hail ; the latter Umits its action to the canton of Neuchatel where moreover it insures only vine-, yards against hail. (i) Monthly Bulletin of Economic and Social Intelligence, November 1915, " Agricixllural Insurance in Switzerland in 1913 ". INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 63 The Zurich society reports having received premiums in 1915 to the amount of 1,298,096 francs ; the Paragrele to the amount of 34,007 francs. These figures are much the same as those for the previous year. Damages amounted for the former society to 1,392,482 francs, for the latter to 316 francs. The Zurich society, which closed its 3^ear's accounts with a loss of 116,921 francs, was informed of some 9000 cases of loss, 1,327 occurring on the single day of 2 August. On this occasion its reserve fund was of great use to it. This had in the previous year been augmented by 603,393 francs derived from surplus receipts. To meet the needs of 1915 the so- ciety drew on it to the extent of 305,662 francs. Its amount at the end of 1915 was 4,490,822 francs as against 3,832,510 francs at the end of 1910. The year 1915 was very profitable to the Paragrele which was appris- ed during its course of only one case of loss. Its reserve fund, already augmented by 9,000 francs in 1914, received almost the total sum of the premiums. Tliis happy event brought its total to 108,750 francs, as against the total of 66,750 francs to which it had been reduced at the end of 1913. NOTICES OF SOME RECENT PUBLICATIONS CONCERNING INSURANCE AND THRIFT. ITALY. MAGAIyDI (V.) : L'Istituto Nazionale delle Assicurazioni. Extract from the Rassegna d'Assi- curazione e Previdenza Sociale, 3'^ year, 16 July 1916, 16 pages. In this interesting pamphlet the author, who for many years has so competent!}' filled the office of General Director of Credit and Thrift in the Ministry of Agriculture, Industrj^ and Commerce, shows that insurance — and especially Ufe insurance — has everj-where greatlj^ developed, and that State intervention has seemed necessar\' for the regulation of its conditions. The legitimate nature of such intervention follows on the fact that free competition does not suffice to prevent the constitution of insurance enterprises which do not technically reach the standard of today and which, by their lack of frankness or even of good faith, cause bitter disap- pointments to the insured persons and thus impede the growth of thrift. Moreover insurance institutions need careful watching, for they accumu- late large capitals which in truth represent the savings of individuals. In Europe the point has not been reached of creating by law pubHc institu- tions charged to insure individuals, save in the case of several tentative efforts, as in Bavaria where b}^ the law of 13 February 1884 a pubUc State institution was formed to insure against damage by hail, and in Switzerland where the compulsory insurance against fire is exercised under the rule of the State monopoly. In Itah' a typical example of institutions of this kind is given by the Istituto nazionale delle assicurazioni, formed by the law of 4 April 1 91 2. This institution enjoys the conditions of a monopoly and practises life insurance in every possible form, the authorization given to private firms, which were legally practising such insurance on 31 De- cember 1911, to continue their activity for ten years from the date of the said law being safeguarded. This national institution, of which this pamphlet makes clear the most saHent characteristics, began work on i January 1913, when it insured capital of the value of 800 million francs, ceded to it by the various ItaHan and foreign companies which had ceased to operate in Italy. Part III: Credit URUGUAY. THE MORTGAGE BANK AND ITvS ACTIVITY IN REI.ATION TO LAND CREDIT IN 1915-1916. SOURCES : De una relacion enviada por la Oficina de EsTADiSTiCA y Publicaciones del Ministerio de Indiistrias de la Republica Oriental del Uruguay al Institute Intern'acional de Agri- cultura [Repot t sent to the International Institute of Agriculture by the Bureau of Statistics with the publications of the Ministry of Industry of the Eastern Republic of Uruguay) . Recently we gave some notes on that reorganization of the Mortgage Bank of Uruguay wliich was decided by the law of 15 October 1915 (i). We then made clear that the essential bases on which the reform of the organization of this establishment was framed were the simultaneous exten- sion of its function in the same direction as that of modern banks, and reinforcement of the safeguards tending to ensure its financial soundness. We will now examine, with the aid of some data sent to us directly by the Ministry of Industry of Montevideo, the results of the activity of this bank in the year 1915-1916 in relation to land credit, with which sub- ject the reform is especially concerned. The figures which we will give cannot of course afford an exact idea of the influence which the reorgan- ization in question may have on transactions, for, as has been said, the law enforcing it was promulgated in October 1915, that is to say when the finan- cial year to which these figures refer was half over. But the figures will (i) See International Review of Agricultural Economics, August 1916, page 78. 66 URUGUAY - CREDIT serve to show the importance of those transactions of the bank which are concerned with land, and also what the bank has done to lessen the distur- bance of the national economy of Uruguay due to local factors, and, even more importantly, to the European conflagration which has profoundly affected all credit transactions in the country. When we come to examine the increase in the operations in land credit conducted by this institution, we find that during the year 1915-1916 the bank made loans of a total value of 3,562,400 pesos (i) as against 2,032,700 pesos in the preceding year, which gives an increase of 1,529,700 ])esos or 75 per cent. This increase is yet more conspicuous if it be remembered that in the year 1914-1915 the requests for rural loans received by the bank from individuals were for a total amount of 5,140,400 pesos and the amount lent was, as has been said, 2,032,700 pesos, while in the year 1915-1916 the total requests were for 8,404,100 pesos and the sums lent amounted to 3,562,400 pesos. Thus in 1914-1915 the loans actually made repre- sented 39 per cent, of those for which application was made, and in 19*5- 1916 42 per cent., a circumstance which proves that the increase in the loans granted last year, as compared with those granted in the preceding year, was due not to greater willingness to accord them but to a greater demand for them. During the year under review the bank granted 157 loans secured by rural mortgages. The average sum lent was 21.62 pesos a hectare (2), and the average annual interest on mortgages was 1.73 pesos. These aver- ages calculated on the hectare, and corresponding to the value of the mort- gaged properties as fixed by the bank's experts and to their annual returns, were 49.29 pesos and 1.99 pesos. The following table gives detailed data with regard to the mort- gages reaHzed by the bank in the nineteen departments of the repubhc of Uruguay. (i) Peso = about 4s 3d at par. (2) I hectare = 2 acres i rood 35.383 poles. THE MORTGAGE BANK AND ITS ACTIVITY 67 Mortgage Loans in 1915-1916. Departments Number of Mortgages Number of Mortgaged Properties Total Area Estimated Value Returns of Properties according to tne Bank Sums for which Proprietors applied Sums lent by the Bank Amount of Annual Interest on Mortgages hectares pesos pesos pesos pesos pesos Montevideo . . 6 8 298 133.331 4,335 62,500 34,000 2.725 Ortigas. . . . 6 6 12,246 339.496 16,841 183,500 169,000 13.549 Camelones . . II 12 2,430 308,123 13.328 164,000 148,800 11,930 Cerro I,argo . 3 3 786 35.004 1,262 20,000 15,000 1,182 Colonia. . . . 12 14 2,489 231.834 8,690 92,500 74,900 6,006 Durazno . . . 7 II 15,249 729,268 23.693 256,000 247,500 19,843 Flores .... 4 4 1,692 130,534 4.960 63,000 49,000 3,928 Florida. . . . 5 5 1,413 91,650 2,968 23,800 15,800 1,266 Maldonado . . 2 9 1,171 45,291 2,251 25,000 19,500 1.563 Minas .... 15 26 8,082 432,364 18,021 256,300 189,200 15.196 Paysandii. . . 34 59 51,715 2,402,418 97.634 1.253.500 1,060,6 0 85.035 Rio Negro . . 8 II 17.674 1,075.758 47,233 615,500 529,000 42,413 Rivera .... 3 3 1,440 46,082 1,824 30,000 22,000 1.763 Rocha .... 4 9 1,902 68,401 2.503 45,000 30,500 2,445 Salto 3 7 17,008 612,817 26,250 3 77,000 331,000 26,538 San Jose . . . II 14 3,135 302,868 13,037 125,000 118,000 9,460 Soriano. . . . 4 4 7.143 434.440 16,144 244,000 183,000 14,672 Tacuaremb6 . 13 22 15,689 589,348 23,206 352,200 275,400 22,105 Treinta y Tres 6 9 3.279 112,390 4.650 102,500 50,200 4,024 Total . . . 157 236 164,750 8,121,427 328,839 4,291,300 3,562,400 285,653 This table shows that while the bank was not niggardly in the matter of granting loans it made them only on the largest and on the safest secu- rity possible. It should be noted that during 1914-1915 the total sum of the loans granted surpassed 100,000 pesos only in seven departments, whereas in the year which ended in 1916 it did so in ten departments. In the two years the total sum of the loans reached its maximum in the departments of , Paysandii . and Rio Negro. 68 URUGUAY - CREDIT If the distribution of loans according to their importance be examined the following facts are obtained : Distribution of Loans according to their Importance. From Categor3- Number of Mort- gages Number of Mort- gaged Proper- ties Amount of I. cans granted Pesos Percentage of Total Amount of Icoans granted 100 to 1,000 pesos . 3 3 2,700 0.08 1,001 » 2,000 » . . 17 17 27,200 0.76 2,001 )) 5,000 » 29 31 124,800 3-50 5,001 » 10,000 )) 45 68 351.800 9.88 10,001 )) 20,000 » 24 45 358.700 10.07 20,001 )) 30,000 » 13 21 330,700 9.28 30,001 » 50,000 » 9 II 400,500 11.24 50,001 )) 70,000 » 2 2 121,000 340 70,001 » 100,000 0 8 13 677,000 19.00 100,001 )) 140,000 » 3 5 366,000 10.27 140,001 )) 200,000 )) 3 16 575.000 16.15 200,001 » 400,000 » I 4 227,000 6-37 Total. • 157 236 3,562,400 We see that the maximum sum of the loans were in the category of those between 70,001 and 100,000 pesos, the average here being 84,625 pesos on a mortgage. However it may be said that the generality of loans, if their amounts be regarded, were in the category of those from 10,000 to 100,000 pesos, which comprises 52.99 per cent, of the total sum lent. As regards the redemption of mortgages the year 1915-1916 gives the following figures : THE MORTGAGE BANK AND ITS ACTIVITY 69 Redemption of Rural Mortgages in 1915-1916. Number Number of of Departments Mortgages Properties Montevideo . . 3 4 Ortegas . . . . I I Camelones . . 9 10 Cerro I^argo . 4 18 Colonia . . . 4 3 Durazno. . . 17 105 Flores. . . . 6 5 Florida . . . 12 30 Maldonado. . 2 2 Minas. . . . 2 3 Paysandti. 3 3 Rio Negro. . 2 2 Rivero . . . . • — — ■ Rocha . . . , — — Salto .... 2 5 San Jose . . 3 6 Soriano . . . 9 6 Tacuarembo . 3 4 Treinta y Tres 2 2 Total. . 84 209 Amount of Loans Percentage Repaid of Total — Sum Repaid Pesos — 23,100 2,24 6,900 0.67 6.4,900 6.29 17,400 1.69 14,200 1.38 187,100 18.13 96,600 Q.36 287,700 27.88 2,300 0.23 9,700 0.94 89,500 8.67 23,900 2.32 23,000 2.23 16,000 1-55 125,800 12.19 39>400 3.89 4,200 0.41 1,031,700 — The maximum number of redeemed mortgages is found in the cate- gory comprising loans of from 30,000 to 50,000 pesos. The redemptions in this category amount to 30.37 per cent, of the total. It should be said however that many loans between 5,000 and 50,000 pesos were repaid, the repayments in this category amounting to 78.75 per cent, of the total. MISCELLANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. DENMARK. THE WORKING OF THE DANISH I,AND CREDIT ASSOCIATIONS IN 191 6. In our issue for April 1911 we published a detailed study of the organi- zation of rural land credit in Denmark; in that for January' 1913 we includ- ed a note on the activity of the Danish land credit associations in 1911-12 ; in that for February 1914 an analogous note on the year 1912-13 ; in that for January 1916 a note on 1914-15. We have now the information which enables us to establish similar statistics for the year 1915-16. To make comparisons easy we have as usual distributed our facts in two tables, of which the second gives statistical information as to land credit associations which grant only loans on first mortgages, while the first includes all the mortgage associations founded with the especial object of granting loans at low rates of interest on second mortgages. It should be remembered that all these associations are based on the principle of mutual sohdarity. It will be seen that the amount of the loans granted on first mortgages by the fourteen associations in the second table was in round figures 1865 million crowns (i) at the beginning of 1916, that is more by 367 million crowns than in 1910. Since several of these associations do not distinguish between urban and rural loans we cannot give exact information as to the debt with which rural landed property is burdened, but it is estimated as half the total debt (2). As regards the activity of the Mortgage Bank of the Kingdom of Den- mark we note that on 31 August 1912 it contracted a new debt of 10,800,000 crowns and was thus enabled to buy from the Treasury bonds for State loans to small farmers {Jordlodder til Landarbejdere) . The bank held on 31 i\Iarch 1915 bonds of associations for land credit to the value of 33, 144,000 crowns, and Jordlodder til Landarbejdere bonds to the value of 16,932,000 crowns. (i) I crown = about is i Y^^d at par. (2) See International Review of Agricultural Economics, 1914, VI. 67. INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT 71 m m m »0 Ov M cr. 0 ON ON ON 0 00 Ov 00 00 00 ON w M t-t w (H VO \o 0 0 >£> vO w M HI l-l M 0 0^ 0 ON ON ON M M W M M 1 1 1 CO fO 1 > 1 vO M ON t-t I fO I t>. On )-• « 3 t3 H s 1-1 c a t^ HI M o o o o U-) N Z o -S 3 S o §•£ § s o •< 3:1 i= M ^' ■^ O <« o a . « £, ■2 03 or ■9 S "e :0 M oJ M ;cj o iH O t3 M ■•« >. .5 = W So" J! .5 l> C -H ^ <^^ t/) (J JS o tn if M i- 03 O oc iT-l -M 2 — ui cc -a "MS 3 C d i3 a '''^ ") is o S <2 ^ C ^ -H" C I" o "o o O i* >, i; .2 .5 M § o ^ N 10 ON N HI HI T^ -^ M HI ■o HI 10 M 0) HI M ^ 10 ON On 72 INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT V 1 c 3 f2 M r- M vO o o M B '^ p t^ o^ >o <3 00 00 U" 00 t>- 00 00 00 00 00 0 H H M H H »H M >o VO vO O « vO u- •a M w w M M ^ m o> o> O o* o> o> a " 'S i: 5 l-l M M 1 M M M o! § o 1 1 ro 1 ro i 1 CO CO 1 ^ 4J H M "^ 1 H 1 O M 1 1 M 1 H 1 ro M fO fO ro ro f M o oc m O •^ o vO t^ c< O N QJ tn lO CO CO 00 c a > U •o o 1 r^ o o CO l-H o t/) ^ N vO c^ c M •-1 ^ «*2 >:: 1 O f; N ■. "oc "o ~5 "o M o O vO in M &A lA fO c^ °°- VO oc vC tH H M a in 'i^ in O c 0 o C a ■^ ^ 00 ■^ t-~ CO rv ra 00_ q. °°. t^ J>. c ■^ a 4h J^ o ^ ON lO •^ N oc oc r- B IH o M •<1- I*- CO ■^ M lO ft- M t^ o c 0 c o t/1 00 o Q 0 c o "rt 1} Si; a > 1 ro w M H oc - c c - rr- O M o 00 o 0^ o 0 *n ''- ;-■ 1 ■^ M »C t^ M o o o a o t^ m" CO -> , , V CS 4) o n , o a! u o o • E • 60 .S ~ w| |3 ^ V a ^ 3 .a V d a 3 O 1 • o -o ■ K a ^ o ^ !:§ c "S D O w a a u V O a s o Q 3 Q a ;-< 4; O .S5 '0 in c s 5 a in _o t p 1 s «4-l a 0 s w a £ 5 C 0/ U o £ "o li p 4j H i 0 41 o a o > 1 4; li 4^ !? 3 V (J o 41 o s ^^ ^1 < a 0 ll V Q 5 w in u 1 in o 1 <2 3 o rt .ti > 0 c o 5 3 o 1 u 1 in s ca o o in e in tn -3 a K '5 '3 c (5 l-< o 3 '7 .2 o o U) in < 5 a a o u 5J v 41 u IH (/) )-< ;-■ IH ll Q w o i^ Ui W M M w t«^ •* tn VO M M M tH H tH tH , 1 1 1 1 04 1 to CO 1 CO j 1 1 l-t M 1 00 M tH ro en CO (N ro CO CO 'i- N M N ■^ r- O 1 lo, ^ r^ 00 N o -^ QN cs o ro ro O O N M (O o ro NO m r^ M lO OC Tjl CO 00 ^ gi ro ro ON tH ro CN| w O Q 00 NO r^ o M cfv o> r-» lO t-t 'T o" (H 00 CO 00 00 "S w o ■o vO 0 t^ 00 o 0^ ON o o t^ lO, o °°. o C^ o 00_ ON X 'sC C~; 00* 00 C^ o M CO ro 0^. ro ^ o CO w u-1 in O , ro 00 hH M 00 ro M- ■^ ! o o 00 o in w IH 0) ro 1 lO ro 1 NO On CO ^ M IH tH X^ 00^ M tH o 2 o o o o O o o o o o o G o_ M 00 00 M o c -r »-l r^ IT) o ■. M 1 1 a! r u- ^ 0 ri ■^ ^ ro M 00 NO u- 1 c-- !>• m H c- , t-l o CM tH •«*• lO d\ t-l 0^ vr ^ oo" vO~ m t-i u-l CM lO <^ CM fl -6 3 1 1 .3 i s 3 "o "s o < s qn H- > 1 o ON lO c^ LI s "3 M C '-a (U •■o 3 p "'5 p u "2 3 '3 5 'w 3 >> o =. _ o .2 in 3 3 o 3 ■J 3 5 3 CO O 1 3 )— 1 tn 1 3 a O 3 '3 C 3 O U c S t« .^ ^ •J} e ^•i >2 O v, tr 1 'C .^ M >^ '? c :0 ■3 'O H U ^ "c i -3 s "S 'C7 :0 ■^ "l 13 "o . "5 i2i S ■X r o V u 3 - 1 I 3 M > c S _S 1 ° p .2 "o o ^ s 1 3 , 3 o j: 's iH • vH ;- p. rr i 1 _0 <2 < ^ 3 > C p. c in < 1 , .^ s O 3 "" t-T V :§ i! ^ u OJ ii ^ u u > iH u ^ Q w 2; w M •^ 1 } o o M M r» CO tH -4- 74 INFORMATION REI^ATING TO CREDIT GERMANY. THE BANK OF THE EANDSCHAFT OF EASTERN PRUSSIA AT KOENIOSBERG IN igi5-iqi6. — Dcr Deutsche Ockonomist, Berlin, 29 July iyi6. When once the pre-war conditions of administrative Hfe had been re- estabHshed in Eastern Prussia economic life could resume a more normal course within this bank's sphere, thanks to State support and to the antici- pated payment of indemnities for losses by the war. The bad harvest of 1915 certainly made recuperation slow, and agriculture had still in many respects to siiffer from the measures rendered necessary by the war. The war gave a particular character to economic life. The flocks and herds could not be maintained at their formier level : in many cases it was impossible to procure manures and concentrated forage in sufficient quan- tities, and on the other hand the sale of live stock and agricultural products reached important dimensions. Many products which were used for pro- duction in time of peace were converted into money which flowed into the banks and savings banks. The quite extraordinary^ increase in the deposits of the Bank of the Landschaft of Eastern Prussia is thus explained. For the same reason a reduction was noticeable in several cases in the investments on current account and other investments, which were transferred to credit accounts : although after recurrent oscillations the total decrease was more important at the end of the year, particularly as a consequence of subscrip- tion to the war loan. The funds entrusted to the bank and the impor- tant sums paid into it by savings banks necessarily remained available owing to their particular character, and were consequently used to buy Prussian and German interest- bearing treasury bonds. At times the bank held more than 47 million marks (i) in these bonds. The issue of bills naturally de- creased owing to the interest taken in the war loans. The banks could there- fore grant considerable quantities of bills at moderate rates, gradually put a term to those financial operations of the Landschaft which were pend- ing at the beginning of the war, and take back the bills issued b}' the Land- schaft. (i) I mark — 11 3/^d. at par. INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT 75 Financial Statement for the year ( i April 1915-31 March 1916). The following are some items from the profit and loss account : Receipts. rt) Profits on Title-Deeds. 1. on title-deeds themselves 8,216.42 maiks 2. on inteiest on title-deeds 526,696.57 » 3. on commissions on operations with ti- tle deeds 66,469.96 » 601,382.95 marks h) On Commission — Commission Account. 1. on advances 17,352.20 marks 2. on deposits 102,613.50 » 3. on mortgage operations 1,199.15 » 4. on sureties 1,765.90 ) 5. on current accovmts 89,469.62 » 6. on various receiving and banking oper- ations 14,201.91 » 226,602.28 » 320,327.14 .) c) On Interest. — Interest Account. d) On Discounting -~ Interest on Securities Account. 1. Interest on securities 301,852.20 marks 2. Interest on treasury bonds 823,041.64 » 1,124,893.84 s e) Excess Profit on Management of Real Estate 47,422.83 » /) On Credit held and redeemed . . 57)7oo-8o » Total Receipts. . . . 2,378,129.84 » 76 INFORMATION REI^ATING TO CREDIT Expenditure. a) Costs of Adininistratio7i {including branches). I. Salaries 243,208.95 £. Indemnities and costs of transcription. 194,010.03 3. Carriage, stamps, telegrams, telephone. 14,899.88 4. Printing and duplicating 22,661.73 5. Heating, light, water 13,153.74 6. Taxes and exchange tax 62,527.11 7. Advertisement, subscriptions to nevvs- Papeis 8,671.59 8. Office material and binding 14,152.73 9. Shaie in costs of the general council of the province and the commission of accoimts 76.00 10. Costs of meetings of general council and travelling exiDenses 2,664.10 11. Travelling expenses and indemnities paid to officials of cential establish- ment and branches 15,796.33 12- Rent 73,615.30 13. Costs and shaie in salaries of I^and- schaft 70,000.00 14. Various 51, 572,. 89 b) Amortization. on moveables 42,482.40 >■ real estate 126,000.00 » current accoimt. . . . '. 121,001.00 » advances 1. 47,110.00 » sureties 10,245.00 various 242,604.47 c) Payments for life insurance of employees. Total expenditure . . . marks 787,010.36 marks 589,442.87 9,637.65 1,386,110.88 » INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT ']'] The excess of receipts over expenditure (profits) amounted thus to 992.018.96 marks, as against 558,313.30 marks in 1914-1915 and 742,926.32 marks in 1913-1914. Deducting the shares due to the dismortgaging funds (21,466.30 marks) and 159,160 marks due to the manager and the employees, we find that the net profits amounted to 811,392.10 marks. This sum is distributed as follows : 1. To the bank's savings reserv^e fund 28,879.11 marks 2. Three quarters to the special fund of the lyand- schaft of East Prussia (entered on debit side of balance-sheet) 586,884.74 » 3. One quarter to the bank's general reserv^e fund 195,628.25 » The Savings Bank. — The Landschaft is responsible for investments in the savings bank, which has the recognized power of receiving trust funds. It had the activity expected of it. In spite of much variation in the sums entrusted to it, owing to the investment of savings in the war loans and the subscription of 4.5 million marks to the third and fourth of these loans, the total amount of savings was increased by about one and a half million marks during the year and was at its close more than nine and a half million marks. The profits of the savings bank were much reduced by the amortization of its title-deeds. The amount of its investments was : on I April 1915 (11,723 savings bank books) 8,027,701.77 marks on 31 March 1916 (13,509 » » « ) 9,605,115.14 » (including credited interest amounting to 319,391.73 marks) The savings reserve fund is invested at the Landschaft in Prussian Ivoan consolidated stock and in the public debt, etc. : Its amount was : on I April 1915 186,097.00 marks on 31 March 1916 (including total profit for 1915- 1916 of 28,879.11 marks) 222,779.10 ;; The bank's general reserve fund passed during the year under review from 961,844.33 marks — including interest and the quarter of the net pro- fits — to 1,199,426.56 marks. The bank's total profit is noticeabl}^ more than in the preceding year, the increase corresponding to that in the circulation of funds and the sums on the balance-sheet. In addition to the profits reahzed as commissions on subscriptions to the war loans, which more than compensated for the depreciation of title deeds by the lowering of the currency, and indepen- dently of the increased profits on other commissions, the increased sum com- ing under the head of interest decided the results of the year. Costs of administration certainly increased noticeably, owing to the increase in taxes, in contributions to enterprises of public utility, etc. Before the bank's net profit was determined sums destined for the amortization of its buildings 78 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO CREDIT and their contents were deducted. 5o,oqo marks was paid into the employ- ee's pension fund, which amounted on i April 1915 to 100,440.67 marks and which, thanks to interest, was 104,180.67 marks at the end of March 1916. If the sum paid into it as above be included, its amount was 154,180.67 marks. As appears from the mortgage account, real estate was mortgaged for 351,000 marks. The office for mortgage loans dealt with operations fewer by 420 than in the previous year. The bank sent to the loan funds all the correspondence and authorities received from those interested in the land register and from the creditors, so as to focus all the register's operations ; and it encouraged recourse to credit by creating second mortgages, together with loans on bills, and by granding extraordinary credits. Part IV: Agricultural Economy in General AUSTRALIA. IvAND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT IN WESTERN AUSTRALIA (concluded) (i) by Dr. J. W. Paterson, Professor of Agriculture in the University of Western Australia. § 3. The provision of credit. Land, labour and capital are the elements of production. With his own hands the settler in Western Australia usually provides his own labour, and the government supplies the land on easy terms ; it also goes a ver>' long way indeed to finance the farmer by means of loans. The Bank Acts. — By the Agricultural Bank Act, 1894, a bank was estabhshed for the purpose of promoting the occupation, cultivation and improvement of farm lands within the State. This Act with a number of subsequent amendments was repealed by a consolidating Act in igo6 which placed the bank on a new footing. Under the new Act the bank was placed under three trustees appointed by the governor in whom is vested the whole of the bank property'. The necessary funds are chiefly provided by the issue of mortgage bonds to the Government Savings Bank at a rate not exceeding 4 per cent. At later dates they have been partially (i) See the first part of this article in our issue for December 1916. 8o AUSTRALIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GEN'ERAL derived from the General Loan Fund at a slightly higher rate of interest. Since its re-constitution under the new Act, the operations of the bank have rapidly increased. The amount authorised to be raised under the 1906 Act was £1,000,000 but by amending Acts of 1907, 1909, 1910, 1912, 1913 and 1914 its capital has been successively raised to its present level of £4,500,000. Objects for ivhichloans are granted. — Under the consoHdating Act of 1906 advances were made to settlers, if the trustees thought fit, for specific objects such as ring-barking, clearing, fencing, draining, water conserva- tion, discharging existing mortgages, also the purchase of stock for breed- ing purposes. Purchase of machinery was added later. Advances to any individual could not exceed £500. Under an amending Act, 1912, the pro- \nsions were extended in various directions and now read as follows : — « Subject to the provisions of this Act the bank may make advances to persons engaged in the business of farming or grazing, or in agricultural, horticultural or pastoral pursuits, to an amount not exceeding £2000, or in any industry that the governor ma}' by proclamation declare to be a rural industr^^ for any purpose incidental to or in aid of any such business, pursuit or industry, including the erection of a dwelling house for the bor- rower on any land occupied or used by him in connection with such business, pursmt or industrs' ». As a matter of fact, however, the main objects for which loans are granted are those named in the original Act. The maximum limit of loans has been greatly increased. Agricultural hank methods. — Applications for loans must be made on a prescribed form and contain full particulars of the objects, such as clearing, fencing, stock, machinery,', etc., for which the advance is required. Each application must be accompanied by a fee of i per cent, of the sum appHed for. Loans are granted for sums of £25 or any multiple thereof, but at no time shall the advances to any one person exceed £2000. The security' taken b}' the bank is a first mortgage over the property. A bill of sale by way of collateral security is required over all stock and machin- ery' purchased with the bank's funds. INIortgages are prepared free of charge to the borrower, but the latter are required to pay the statutory fees for registration of their securities, amounting to a few shilUngs. The whole amount of an approved loan need not be paid at once, but progress pa3'ments are made against improvements on the certificates of approved neighbouring landholders. This last provision has sometimes been abused. The minimum instalment of a loan payable at one time is £10. Relation of hank to the settler. — The contact of bank and borrower begins with the occupation of the land, but crown lands being valued and classified prior to selection, the bank is enabled to give an opinion quickly before the settler selects the land. While the trustees are empowered to fix advances on land, it is not obligatory on them to do so in ever}- case. They may use their own discretion when the security is considered unsafe either on account of the inferior quality of the land, inadequate area for maintenance of a home, situational disadvantages, or, in the case of special advances, low sale value or insufficient development. Needless to sa3% I.AND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT selectors almost invariabh^ choose a block which will carry an advance from the bank. Loans, once made, are only Hable to recall for breaches of the mortgage covenant. Rates of interest, surrender of securities etc. — Loans made for improve- ment purposes carry interest at the rate of 5 per cent, per annum. The rate chargeable on advances made for other purposes, such as stock, machinery etc. , is 6 per cent, per annum. Interest is calculated on the daily balance and is payable on the first day of January and the ist. of Juty in each j^ear. A closing fee of IDS. 6d. is pa3^able on the discharge of ever>' mortgage, and a production charge of 5s. is made in connection with the lodgement of documents of title for the registration of outside dealings. Currency of loans. — All loans made against improvements have a currency of thirty 3'ears, and are amortisable by fiftj^ equal half -3' early instal- ments, the interest only being payable for the first five years. Stock and machiner\' loans are repayable b}' ten equal half-3^early instalments com- mencing three years from date of making the advance. It is, however, the privilege of the borrower to repa3' the whole or an3' portion of the loan at an3' time without notice. A typical transaction. — The following entries in connection with an advance to a settler in the Coorow district will serve to illustrate the nature of the improvements effected and the S3^stem of progress payments. Ever3' inducement is offered to the new settler by prompt progress pay- ments, so that on taking up land he ma3' immediateK' find emplo3'ment as his own master. 82 AUSTRALIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Transactions in connection with loan of £500. cooRow district. ist. Loan, £125 approved. Date Payments Improvements 29-7-08 £30 Well, 35 ft. 26-8-08 25 Fence, 80 chains, 6 wires at 6s, 6d. 8-£0-o8 20 Fence, 53 chains, 6 wires at 6s. 6d. — — Ring and scrub 70 acres at 3s, 6d. 3-10-10 15 Clearing 10 acres. — — Ring and scrub 30 acres. 17-5-11 35 Clearing 35 acres. £125 2nd. Loan approved. 26-9-10 44 Fencing 147 chains, 6 wires at 6s. 9-1-11 146 Clearing 10 acres at 20s. 21-2-11 60 Clearing 140 acres at 20s. — — Fencing 150 chains, 6 wires at 6s. 4-4- II 25 Fencing 103 chains, 6 wires at 6s. — — Well, 28 ft. timbered. £27: ;^rd. Loan approved. 2-3-11 100 Mares Total . . . £500 Stock and machinery loans are granted in the wheat areas only when 250 acres, worth 20s. per acre, have been cleared and rendered fit for the plough. lyoans for the purchase of stock and machinery are limited to £100. Extent of the bank's operations. -~ The following statement, compiled from the annual report of the trustees, shows the total amounts advanced to farmers up to 30 June of each of five years, the amounts repaid and the outstanding balances at the same dates. IvAND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT 83 Table VII. — Operations of agricultural bank 1910-14. 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 Advances to date Repayments to date Outstanding Balances £ £ 1,257,082 1,540,241 321,122 563,430 935,960 976,811 i £ 1,946,184 665,452 1,280,732 £ 2,582,937 698,980 1.883.957 £ 3>o89,575 757,624 2,331.951 With the wider objects for which the bank now grants loans, the greater maximum advance made possible by the amended (1912) Act, and above all owing to the greater number of settlers, the operations of the bank have steadily increased during recent years. Purpose Of the bank loans. -■ Advance?; may be made for effecting certain improvements already referred to, and also to a more limited extent for the purchase of stock or implements. Advances may also be made to lift existing mortgages to private institutions to an amount not exceeding three fourths of the value of the improvements already made on the holding, but purchase money is not regarded as a liability under the Act. The following table shows the various purposes to which bank ad- vances were applied during the year ending June 1913. The last column of the table shows the total amount which had been expended on the several objects up to date. Table VIII. — Purposes to ivhich hank advances were applied. For year ending 30 June Total amount to date Liabil'ties taken over £124,056 67,941 9,732 435,024 £231,353 246,495 6,494 14.578 3.278 2,080,739 For purchase of stock For purchase of plant For purchase of implements For purchase of fertilisers For developmental purposes £636,753 £2,582,937 The amotmt s])ent on the development or improvement of farms co\-ered a variety of items. As usual the estimated value of the improve- 84 AUSTRALIA - AGRICULTUR.\L ECONOMY IX GENERAL ments was considerably greater than the bank advances given to effect them. Table IX taken from the report shows the value of these improve- ments during the same year. The last column also shows the value of the several improvements effected by the help of the bank up to date. Table IX. — Improvements effected laith the assistance of bank funds. For year ending 30 June Total amount to date Clearing Culti%'ating Ring-barking & scrubbing . . Fencing Draining Water supply Buildings Orchard Blackboy & poison grubbing 285,350 360 338,816 chains 227,815 acres 10,529 £ 289,066 no 97,429 68,145 286 35,096 3,207 1,606 1,174.521 214,398 1,706,435 chains 1,452,918 321 £494,945! costing £ 1,471,636 120,572 246,4 72 429,782 5,945 138,615 87.075 4,321 13,786 £2,518,204 Proportion of loans granted. — During the year ending 30 June the board of trustees held fifty meetings and dealt with 4,009 ap})lications from new and old clients, aggregating £923,885. The loans authorised numbered 3,442 involving a sum of £660,765. Of these, sixty-three applications representing the sum of £11,159, were subsequently cancelled at the appUcants' request, and undrawn loans to the value of £155,734 were also cancelled, leaving a net capital appropriation of £493,872 for the year. Applications amounting to £184,255 were declined in full. Number of clients. — The accoxmts closed during the financial year I913 aggregated 133 as against 461 for the preceding term. New accounts to the number of 1358 were opened, making the total number of accounts, current as on 30 June, 8326, and the average amount of borrowers' balances £226 5s. 6d. Loans to farmers in other States. — In each of the Australian vStates the local government has established a system under which financial aid LAND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT 85 is rendered to the farmers. In every instance the scale of operations has steadily increased in magnitude during recent years, and in 1914 involved a large outstanding balance. The position of Western Australia relatively to the other States will be gathered from the following tables which are compiled from figures furnished b3^ the Government Savings Bank of Victoria. Table X. — Government advances to farmers (1909-10 to 1913-14). state Aggregate advanced to 30 June 1 910 igll 1912 1913 Iyl4 N. S. Wales (i) 1,362,853 1,617,192 1,948.885 2,423.955 3,531,263 Victoria Queensland S. Auitralia (2) " W. Australia Tasmania Common wealt h 2,657,713 2,797,323 2,954,618 235,793 306,944 430,403 i,544,946| 1,786,762 i,25y,o82f 1,540,241 9.1S7 7,067,574 14,610 2,064,583 3,208,9031 3,491,008 623,498 851,600 2,370,076 2,601,450 1,946,184, 2,582,937 3,089,575 18,636 8,063,072 9,363,309 23,915 11,233,284 41,004 13,605,900 (i) For years ending December prior, except for year 1914. (2) Includes loans to other producers arui to local bodies on the security of their oxvn rates. All of the States have made heavy advances to their farmers. Deduct- ing the amounts of loan moneys repaid in the several States at different dates from the amounts advanced, the outstanding balances have been estimated. The facts are stated in Table XL 86 AUSTRALIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Tai3LE XI. — Government loans to farmers (iQog-io to 1913-14). Balance outstanding at 30 June 1912 N. S. Wales (i) . . . . Victoria Queensland S. Australia (3) . . . . W. Australia Tasmania Commonwealth (2) 795,113 (2) 1,308,425 163,640 710,316 935,960 8,521 928,086 1,306,657 206,997 819,818 gy6,8ii 13,561 1.074.358 1.343,834 305.652 966,670 1,280,732 16,592 3,921,975 4,251,930 4,987,838 1.396,336 1,511,798 470.795 1,150,020 i,S83,957\ 21,089 2,297,981 1,676,432 636,790 1,264,417 2,331,959 36,965 6,433.9951 8,244,544 (i) At 31 Dec. prior, except in 1914. (2) After deduction of special principal payments in advances. (3) Includes balances to farmcis, and other producers and to local bodies on the security of the At the latest date for which returns common to the States are avail- able. Western Australia had greater outstanding balances with its farmers than any other State. Loan operations relatively to number of farms. — When the loan oper- ations of the bank are contrasted with those of the other States, the figures become still more striking when account is taken of the actual number of farmers in the various States. In Table XII are stated the total number of holdings of all sizes alienated or in process of alienation in the several States in 1914, the outstanding loan balances in the same year, and finally the amount which each farm would carry if the balance in each State were equally distributed among the holdings. The data for Queens- land are not available. LAND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT 87 Table XII. — Government loans and number of holdings (1914). N. S. Wales Victoria (i) . S. Australia . W. Australia Tasmania . . Number of holdings 92,665 66,811 21,369 15,620 13,371 Balances outstanding 2,297,981 1,511,798 1,264,417 2,331,959 36,965 Calculated loan advance per holding 24.8 22.6 592 149-3 2.8 (I) 1913- Such a comparison gives a general view of the situation, but lays no claim to completeness. It embraces all holdings irrespective of size, and some vStates have a greater preponderance of small holdings than others Examination of the details show that Western Australia has relatively somewhat fewer of the smaller sizes than the oldei States. Its differences in this respect, are, however, trivial when compared with the proportionate advance per holding, and it is clear, therefore, that in proportion to their numbers, the government there has gone much further in providing credit for its farmers than have those of the .sister States. Newness of farms in Western Australia. — The results found in the preceding paragraph pay, at first sight, a poor compliment to the farming conditions prevalent within the State. It should be recollected, however, that agriculture in Western Australia is very largely a new development, and that its operations (Table I.) and its number of holdings (Table VI) have increased with great rapidity during recent years. The newness of its agriculture is also indicated by the rapid increase in the area of its lands already alienated or in the process of alienation (Table V). This increase is not onh' relatively, but also absolutely, greater than the corres- ponding increase in any other State. This can be seen from the following statement where the total area of land ahenated and in process of alien- ation is stated for each State at 1901 and again at 1913 - the last year for which complete data are available. 88 AUSTRALIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOM V IN GENERAL Table XIII. — Lands alienated and in process of alienation in the different States at different dates. state I^ands alienated & in process of alienation Increase in 12 yrs N. S. Wales Victoria . . Queensland . S. Australia . W. Australia Tasmania . . 48,039,242 23,797,226 16,325,132 8,088,897 9,585.144 4.893,961 57,818,023(1) 31,171,956 26,081,018 12,451,709 21,362,546 (i) 6,341,817 9,778,781(0 7.374.730 9,755,886 4,362,712 ii,y7y,402{2 1,447,856 (i) To 30 June. (2) In II V2 years. Government loans are not intended to bolster up incompetent farmers in old settled districts, but to finance new enterprise and open up new fields for the settler. Regarded in this light, the table shows that of late years Western Australia has taken a lead in the establishment of new farms, and consequently has had heavy demands made upon her credit. Reference to Table XI shows that at the date of the latest returns her existing loans to settlers exceeded those of anv other State. § 4. Conclusion. Land settlement has proceeded in the vState with great rapidity partly for technical and economic reasons previously discussed, but very largely also as a result of the vigorous land policy of successive governments, and the liberal character of its agricultural loans. Whether in certain in- stances its land policy has been too vigorous and its loan system too generous, are matters with which this article is not intended to deal. Its object is to record facts. Present indications suggest that the loan policy will be modified at an earlj' date owing to the growing stringency of the money market resulting from the war. Effect of curtailing loans. — Should the loan policy of the government be curtailed for the reason stated, it is possible that a number of new settlers, possessing no resources other than their credit with the bank, I,AND SETTLEMENT AND THE PROVISION OF CREDIT 89 may repudiate their obligations and abandon their holdings. This is the prime danger of a generous loan policy which, if carried too far, may de- feat its own end. The bank holding the mortgage can, of course, sell any properties reverting to it with the improvements thereon. As the advances were made against the improvements, it need not necessarily incur loss. It may do so, however, and it will lose the settler. During 1914, eighty securities reverted to the bank in this way, fourteen unsold properties were carried over from the previous 3'ear, and sixty were resold, within the year. If the bank's operations must necessarily be curtailed, the number of those resales is almost certain to increase in the future. Prospects for the future. — Under the conditions indicated, a premium will be placed upon the possession of private capital by new settlers seeking for land in Western Australia. At the present time good wheat lands are very appreciabl}^ cheaper there than similar lands in the eastern States. Should a period of temporary depression now supervene, in the event and as the result of curtailments by the bank, the difference will become relatively greater. Depreciation of land values in the west can be only temporar3^ At the time of writing the wheat yield of the State for 1915 is officially estimated at 13.5 bushels per acre over a record area. A factor likely to affect prices in the future and promote settlement is the opening of land connection with the eastern States over the trans-continental railway promised for the close of the present year. RUSSIA. THE RKSUIvTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINI.AND. {Concluded) (i). § 5. The component parts of the property of coeonists. Having distinguished between the two factors in colonization in Fin- land, the man and the land, and studied them in every aspect, we will now turn our attention to the results of their joint action, and the question of whether or to what extent they advance the work of colonization. We will do it best by inspecting more closely the individual forms of capital which go to make the complex assets and h abilities of farming and also the capital invested in households, secondary businesses and the like. From the increase and decrease of such capital and groups of capital, from the changes suffered by all assets from the time the colonists' lots were taken over until the close of the enquiry, we will attempt to construct a picture of the results attained by the new Finnish colonists and of their limitations. We will examine the component parts of the property in the order in which these were placed at the eiid of § 2. I. Capital in real estate of the farms. The capital in real estate is composed of capital in land, capital in soil and capital in buildings. a) Capital in land. When the lots were taken over the average gross price a hectare (2) for the total 219,628 hectares comprised by all the land of the colonies, and for the appurtenant buildings, woods and hunting and fish- ing rights, varied according to the grant from yy to 136 Finnish marks (3). The average price a hectare in the seven colonies investigated was, as we have already seen (4), 86 Finnish marks, that is 22 per cent less than the general price. The price of land was of course distincly higher in the case of torp holdings which had already been long settled before the beginning of the (i) The first part of this article appeared our issue for November 191 6. (2) A hectare = 2 acres i rd. 35.383 pos. (3) 1.2611 Finnish marks = is at par. (4) International Review of Agricultural Economics, November 1916, page 119. THE RESTJLT OF INTERIOR COI.ONIZATION IN FINI.AND QI colouizing enterprise, than in that of the newly allocated lots : it was in the case of the former, according to facts furnished by the Finnish lease offices (Helsingfors 1915), 642 marks for a hectare of arable land near the demesne land of the estate, and varied according to its situation from 423 to 783 Finnish marks. For abandoned torp lands the price varied from 328 to 528 Finnish marks. For meadowland near the demesne land of the estate an average price of 333 Finnish marks a hectare was paid and for meadows some- what remote that of 239 Finnish marks a hectare. The average price for a hectare of woodland was, according to its situation in relation to the demesne land of the estate and according to the grant, from 163 to 125 Fin- nish marks. A comparison of these prices with those obtaining in Russia proper when the new agrarian reforms were carried out, or those accompany- ing the colonization of new lands in other countries, shows that hitherto colonizing enterprise in Finland has succeeded in securing land at relatively low prices, and shows too the circumstance, connected with this one, that the prices of land in Finland are as yet generally lower than in other countries. During the time of the enquiry the following alterations took place in capital in land. By the inclusion of woodland the possible taxable value of arable and meadowland in the investigted colonists' lots rose by '>,'] Finnish marks a lot. As a result of permanent improvements — such as breaking new land and clearing it of stones, the construction of larger drainage ditches, the laying out of gardens, the addition of loam to moorland soil — the capital in land increased in value by 176 Finnish marks a lot. Altogether the value of the capital in land rose during the time of the enquiry by 18,113 Finnish marks, an average of 213 Finnish marks a lot, or of 8.95 Finnish marks per hectare of arable and meadowland. The average yearly increase in the value of the land of the colonies was 44 Fin- nish marks for each lot, 7 Finnish marks of this sum having arisen by an extension of area at the expense of woodland and 37 by permanent improvements of the soil. b) Capital in soil. According to the author's investigations the most important part of capital in soil consists of the value of manure. When the land was taken over the total value of the manure was 76.2 per cent, of that of the capital in soil ; at the end of the enquiry it was 58.3 per cent. The relative value of the manure was lower when the enquiry closed than when farming began because the earlier computation was made in spring, the later on i July. The total capital vahie and the percentage of it represented by manure varies not only in the different colonies but even more in the different lots within one colony. This is because some lots were made on settled lan(f, previously cultivated and therefore more or less manured ; while others were made on virgin soil. The succession of crops has contributed to the same end. The total value of the stock in cultivated soil when the lots were taken over averaged 411 Finnish marks a lot, and 1,161 Finnish marks on i July. The total increase in capital value during the period of enquiry amounted 92 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL to 69,779 Finnish marks, namely an average of 750 Finnish marks a lot, or 155.38 Finnish marks for a hectare of arable land and 67.36 Finnish marks for a hectare of arable and meadowland. A relative diminution of capital in soil is to be noted in Koskipaa colony, where owing to the remoteness of the arable land, as compared with the other colonies, and the preva- lence of the three field system, the live stock could not be increased as much as elsewhere. The increase in value of capital in soil, both annual and total,^can be seen from the following table. Increase in Value of Capital in Soil. Total increased Value Finnish. marks Annual increased Value Components By hectare | By hectare of arable ■°y '°* of arable land | and meadowland of Capital in Soil Finnish p-rcent ^^innish marks ^^ercent. ^^^^^ Percent. ^^S percent. In a number of years. Total value of manvire Costs of clearing dit- ches Costs of laying out clo- ver grass fields . . . Costs of transporting loam 30,952 2,537 2,744 1,187 87 6 7 3 50.6 3-5 4.0 1-7 8.54 0.94 0.92 0-34 42.7 4-7 4.7 1.7 7-55 0.60 0.60 0.25 49.2 3-9 3-9 1.6 In one year. Costs of labour . . . Seeds Manures 13,431 ".275 1,635 35 30 4 20.5 17.4 2.3 4-57 4-15 0.52 22.8 20.8 2.6 323 2.77 0-34 21. 1 18.1 2.2 Total . . . 63,779 172 1 00.0 19.98 lOO.O 15-34 1 00.0 The annual increase in value of the capital in soil averaged 172 Finnish marks for a single lot, 19.98 Finnish marks for a hectare of arable land, and 15.34 Finnish marks for a hectare of arable and meadowland taken together. If the lots be classified according to their size the capital in soil at the end of the period of enquiry is found to average as follows for one hec- tare of arable land : In lots having an area of less than 2.5 hectares — 350 Finnish inks, for " " " " " " from 2.5 to 5 " — 201 " " " " " " " " " 5 " 7.5 " — 158 " " " " " " " 7.5 " 10 " — 155 " " " " " " 10 " 15 " — 161 " " " " " " " " 15 and more " — 173 " " hectare THE RESUI^TS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINI.AND 93 Thence it appears that the vahie of the capital in soil in the smaller hold- ings, those of less than 5 hectares, is relatively greater than it is in the larger farms ; a circumstance due, according to the author, to the fact that on the smaller holdings live stock is relatively more numerous than on the large farms. c) Capital in buildings. When the 85 lots which were investigated were taken over the value of the capital in buildings was as follows : Buildings appurtenant to the lots 17,660 Finnish marks Buildings taken over with the land 39, 801 Taxable value of sites of premises and of roads . . 630 Total . . . 58,091 On I July 1912 the value of such capital had risen as follows : Buildings 187,867 Finnish marks Taxable value of sites of premises and of roads 1,299 " " Total . . . 189,166 Thus the total increase in value was 131,075 Finnish marks. If the average for a single lot be calculated it is found to be as follows : When the lots were taken over. — Buildings appurtenant to them 208 Finnish marks Buildings taken over with the land 468 Taxable value of sites of premises and of roads. . 7 Total ... 683 On I July 1912. Buildings 2,210 Finnish marks Taxable value of sites of premises and roads . . 15 " " Total . . . 2,225 The average increase in value on a lot is therefore 1,542 Finnish marks. These figures are to be regarded as representing the addition made to the value of the capital in buildings solely by the colonists' activity in farm- 94 RUSSIA - AGRICUI,TURAI< ECONOMY IN GENERAIv ing their holdings during the period of the enquiry. The market value of the buildings — the effect of a general rise in prices — has been disregarded in accordance with the aim of the whole enquiry as already stated. As regards single colonies the increase in value of capital in buildings was greatest in vSeppala, where it averaged 2,758 Finnish marks a lot ; and least in Nipuli, the average there being 427 Finnish marks a lot. The num- ber of dwelling houses on the 85 lots investigated was 98 and they comprised 224 rooms. Thus there was an average of 2.5 weather-tight rooms for each lot and 2.3 for each dwelling house. An average of 255 cubic metres, measurements being taken outside, was devoted to dwelling house room on each lot, namely 236 cubic metres to Uving-rooms and kitchens and 19 cubic metres to masonr3\ On an average 2.2 members of a family inhabited each living-room, 1.7 being over twelve years old. In all the 85 lots there were 188 stables and byres, that is an average of 2.2 a lot. This average is high because, as already stated, many colonists' lots have arisen out of earlier torp holdings which usually included several buildings. The buildings for storage comprised, when measured from outside, an average of 62 cubic metres for each lot, storerooms, granaries and cellars being included. The value of buildings averaged for each member of a family 175 Fin- nish marks, or 270 for each of such of them as were over twelve years old. The author observes that these figures represent very low values even according to Finnish standards ; and that in the case of capital in buildings, as in that of capital in land, colonizing enterprise in Finland has succeeded in keeping costs very low, especially where it has been possible to bu}' up older build- ings cheaply. 2. Farming Capital. The farming capital of the colonists can be analysed as capital in machines and implements, in live stock, in other stock, in shares in the co-operative funds and in cash. We will briefly consider these components individually. a) Capital in machines and implements. When the colonists' lots were taken over the machines and implements were worth 15,642 Finnish marks. During the course of the enquiry their value rose to 22,439 Finnish marks and on i July 1912 it had reached the sum of 38,081 Finnish marks. Its greatest increase in value up to that date occurred in Seppala colony, where it was 735 Finnish marks, its least in Nipuli colony where it was 199 Finnish marks. The average annual increase in the different classes of property forming capital in machines and implements, on a single lot and on a hectare of arable and meadowland, can be shown as follows : THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 95 Per single lot Finnish marks Per hectare of arable and meadowland Finnish marks 8.15 14-25 2.40 075 11.30 14.60 1-75 6.10 0.74 1-33 0.20 Inventory of stables 0.03 103 1.28 Invi ntory of dair>' Carts etc Housi hold implements Othi-r implements 0.14 0.56 Total . . . 59.30 531 The total value of the machines and implements increased on an aver- age during the period of enquiry by 264 Finnish marks for each single lot or by 23.43 Finnish marks for a hectare. If the various values of the capital in machines and implements in the investigated lots be compared with the size of the holdings, it appears that such capital is notably greater in the larger than in the smaller of these ; yet when the average for a single hectare of arable and meadowland is calculated there is no great difference in value to be observed. These facts appear from the following table : Average Cask value of Machines and Implements according to the Size of the Colonists' Lots and for 1 hectare of Arable and Meadowland. Area of lots No. of lots Average value in Finnish marks Arable and meadowland For a single lot For I hectare of arable and meadowland Up to 2.5 hectares . . . From 2.5 to 5 » ... » 5 » 7.5 » ... » 7.5 » 10 •> ... » 10 » 15 » ... » 15 » 25 !> ... 25 and more » : . . 2 II 22 II 22 13 3 257 148 368 378 501 757 800 115 35 55 42 40 43 20 For whole area . . . 85 448 42 96 RUSSIA - AGRlCuivTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL b) Capital in live stock. The capital in live stock rose in value between the time when the lots were taken over and that at which the enquiry was completed from 53,549 to 100,190 Finnish marks. Thus the increase was one of 47,641 Finnish marks or 87.1 percent. The average value on each lot, when taken over, of this capital was 630 Finnish marks, and on i July 1912 it was 1,179 Finnish marks. For a hectare of arable and meadowland the average value was 63.38 Finnish marks at the earlier and 110.37 Finnish marks at the later date. The live stock was of least value in Siika- jarvi, where it averaged 651 Finnish marks a lot, and of greatest value in Koskipaa, where it averaged 2,245 Finnish marks a lot. The total increase in the value of the capital in live stock averaged 549 Finnish marks a lot, varying from 145 to 983 Finnish marks in the different colonies. If the live stock be divided into the two groups of cattle and horses, and their value from the time when the colonies were first established until the close of the period of enquiry be calculated, the average increase in their respective values on a single lot and on a hectare of arable and meadowland is as follows : Cattle. For a lot » I hectare arable and mead- owland Percentage of whole capital in live stock Horses. For a lot » I hectare arable and mead- owland Percentage of whole capital in live stock When land was taken over Finnish marks 429 43-25 68% 201 20.13 31.9 % I July 1912 Finnish marks 763 71.44 64-7 % 416 38.93 35-3% Amount of increase Finnish marks 334 28.19 215 18.80 It thus appears clearly that the capital in live stock has greatly in- creased on the colonists' lots. The value is distributed among the groups of holdings, classified according to size, as follows : THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 97 The Capital in Live Stock on Holdings of Different Sizes. No. of lots Average value per Area of arable and meadowlana Lot I hectare arable and meadowland Up to 2.5 hectares . From 2.5 to 5 » » 5 » 7.5 » • • » 7.5 » 10 » » 10 » 15 » 15 » 25 » 25 and more 2 II 22 12 22 13 3 551 613 801 925 1,387 1,766 3,337 248 152 116 107 115 105 90 For whole area . • • 85 1,179 no c) The capital in other stock. Unlike the capital in the groups hitherto examined that in stock other than live stock has remained unaltered on the colonists' farms, and is even found to have undergone a slight diminution if its average for one hectare be reckoned. This is chiefly due to the circumstance that the inventory was taken at the end of the period of enquiry and therefore in the summer, a time when stock is notoriously at its lowest in farms. Further the beds of manure were reckoned as constituting not capital in stock but capital in soil. In the 85 lots investigated the capital in stock was of the value of 8,882 Finnish marks, averaging 105 Finnish marks for a lot and 10.51 for a hec- tare of arable and meadowland. The increase relatively to the outgoings varied according to the colonies. In NipuU and Kaskipaa colonies the capital in stock diminished in va- lue from 103 to 80 Finnish marks a lot, while in Seppala and Sippola it increased from 92 to no Finnish marks. The increase depends cliiefly on the presence of woodland products, such as firewood, building materials, etc. d) Co-operative shares and cash. The co-operative shares of the colonists on the investigated lots were very trifling : when the land was taken over their value averaged 3 Fin- nish marks for a lot and, on i July 1912, 13 Finnish marks, giving an in- crease of 10 Finnish marks. In Sippola and Kaskipaa such average value was almost three times that of the general average, being 27 and 29 Finnish marks,but in Muddais on the other hand there was no co-operative enterprise whatsoever. As regards capital in cash it was naturally greater when the lots were taken over than on i July 1912, when the enquiry closed. The money which 98 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL the colonists brought with them came, during the time of the enquiry, to be represented by the different forms of capital invested in the farm. When the land was taken over the capital in cash amounted to 11,296 Finnish marks, averaging thus 133 Finnish marks for a lot and 13.25 for a hectare of arable and meadowland. In Koskipaa the colonists possessed more than the average sum, namely on an average 224 Finnish marks a lot ; in Siika- jarvi the average amount possessed on a lot was less than the general aver- age, being not more than 30 Finnish marks. On I July 1912 Koskipaa colony still held most capital in cash, aver- aging 177 Finnish marks a lot ; while Nipuli, where such average was only 48 Finnish marks, held least. For all the colonies the decrease in capital in cash per lot varied from 37 to 107 Finnish marks and averaged 43. An increase in the average amount of cash held with a lot occurred only in Mud- dais and Siikajarvi colonies. 3. Capital not directly invested in Farming. The changes suffered by capital not directly invested in the farms, but connected with the agriculture of the colonists and therefore influencing the course and the results of their farming activities, will be mentioned shortly. a) The capital in household goods and implements had the following value : When the land was taken over Household goods 3, 519 Finnish marks implements. . . 2,139 » » 5,658 Finnish marks On I July 191 2 » goods 3,592 » » implements. . . 5,695 » » 9,287 Total increase in value 3,629 » » The increase is chiefly due to a multiplication of implements. The yearly increase averages 9 Finnish marks for a lot and 0.79 Finnish marks for an acre of arable and meadowland. b) The capital invested in other businesses decreased in the course of the enquiry from 34,590 to 9,692 Finnish marks ; and such decrease was made largely at the expense of the money invested in banks. When the land was taken over the savings deposits of the colonists averaged 280 Finni.sh marks for each lot ; and on i July 1912 the deposits had been almost THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 99 entirely withdrawn, and the average amount remaining in the banks was for each lot only 38 Finnish marks. On the other hand the sum paid for life insurance rose during the period of enquiry from 1,020 to 1,790 Fin- nish marks, that is by 779 Finnish marks, an average of 9 marks for a lot. When the land was taken over the average amount of capital invested in other businesses was 407 Finnish marks for each lot. In Muddais colony it was highest, namely 1,023 Finnish marks; in Siikajarvi it was lowest — 66 Finnish marks. In 1912 the average for a lot had fallen to 115 Finnish marks. The author reckons as capital in other businesses that invested in accessory industries and leasehold and other rights. c) The capital in personal belongings, such as clothes and furniture, was worth 28,484 Finnish marks when the land was taken over, giving an average of 335 marks for a farm or family. On i July 1912 it had not no- tably increased, being 33,269 Finnish marks, which gave an average of 391 marks for a family. The annual increase therefore averaged 11 marks for a lot and seems very trifling. The reason for its slightness is, according to the author, that after the lots had been taken over the colonists were much occupied in setting their farms in order and had little time in which to supply themselves with clothes, furniture and other personal possessions. d) The service of paying woodland dues, that is woodland rents and amortization payments attached to the earlier debt with which woods were burdened, was during the period of the enquiry of the value of 30,615 Finnish marks, an average of 360 marks for a lot and of 33.72 for an acre of arable and woodland. Payments of this description are highest in Koskipaa colony where they average 1,053 Finnish marks a lot, and lowest in Siikajarvi and Nipuli where they average 214 Finnish marks a lot. Finally as regards hereditary payments and presents these occurred in onty three colonies — Siikajarvi, Nipuli and Koskipaa — and amounted to 3,580 Finnish marks. In the following table all the capital of the colonists represented b}^ their farming, before and after the lands were taken over and on i July 1912, is set out. 100 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENER.'^L « HI >. 3 l-> n o Per- centage 1 i Ji 1 tx Mfn oKi-idK M 11 C^ i-i N § Average per hectare of arable and mead- owland III ^ r*1 ^NO -*f^M VO" tx <>. w -a- « « hT C^ M* 1 H ' ' 1 i 1 00 Ol>0 mOOvINMI 1 « to c^ oo" d oo" M fC 1 1 m >0 Co to O 1 o S t i a < to 6 ■* 1 Average per hectare of arable and mead- owland ^ § o m to CO tn -^ M oo M in m 1 to t> «^ oi u, to r. 00 =0 00 to o o to IT) 1 VO M ^O HC M 1 to s ft ^ 11^- sis N M 1 to -4- to rj- O « to to t^ 1 Oo 00 CO O to 1 rt 1 vo oo 1 1 « '°- 0\ 00 i| 00 \n N c< oi t< g\ lO o o. * -* oo o\ oi oo 1 o vo m 00 « N oo" oo" in to oo" m" to in M m M i-i 1 > o s a V 1 PQ ft g m m 1 1 lO to 1 1 M cc o o ■n in q to c; in j 1 1 id * 6 oo" 6 6 ! 1 Average per hectare of arable and mead- owland lis 1 o Ol t o IH 00 M m m 1 1 ^ "? "? *? fJ O 00 to O O CO 1 V oo m lis ^ "8 00 ll- o m to to 1 1 1 O 00 to o to 1 1 1 « « lO M M 1 o H 1 1 t^ Ol I-I 00 00 lO ^ ^ OO ON Ol 1 1 lo lo m 00 « N 1 1 tC in to oo « H M in 1- , a 1 r ^ 1 ft != 0 ft 'J Capital in land : Capital in land . . . Increased va- lue of capi- tal in soil . Capital in buildings . Farming ca- pital: Machines and imple- ments. . . Live stock . Other stock. Co-operative shares . . Cash . . . . S \ o ^ 1 THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND lOI § 6. The LIABILITIES OF THE COLONISTS. During the period of enquiry into the colonists' lots not only the property but also the liabilities of the colonists underwent changes, in the manner which will now be described. 1. The State debt on the land. When the colonists were settled the vState granted the lots as bearing their full taxable value. The amount with which the farms (woodland being excepted) on the 85 investigated lots were burdened was 174,236 Finnish marks, giving an average of 2,049 Finnish marks for a lot and 206.19 Finnish marks for a hectare of arable and meadowland. This debt on the land (prior debt) has been lessened by annual payments in redemption, but on the other hand has been increased when woodland has been subjected to agriculture and the area farmed thus extended. Altogether the debt to the State has diminished only by 4,826 Finnish marks, giving for each lot an average decrease of 56 marks. These low figures are explained by the circumstance that the State, in the first years after the lots had been taken over, did not compel the colonists to make payments in redemption. At the end of the period of enquiry this prior debt was of 169,410 Finnish marks, giving an average of 1,993 marks for a lot and 186.57 ^o^ a hectare of arable and woodland. 2. Loans from hanks and private persons. Debts of this category have dur- ing the period of enquiry altered, in respect of their total amount and the average for a single lot and for a hectare of arable and meadowland, as follows : I02 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL When the land was taken over Finnish marks 1 1 On I Julj' iyi2 ! Increase Finnish marks Finnish marks Total amount. Debts to banks Other debts 3,Olo 5,080 17,475 24,436 14,465 19,466 Total . . . 8,090 42,091 33,931 Average per lot. Debts to banks Other debts 35 60 205 289 170 229 Total . . . 95 494 399 Average per hectare of arable and meadowland. Debts to banks Other debts 356 6.01 19.24 27.03 15.68 21 02 Total . . . 9-57 46.27 36.70 Most colonists have received credit from the co-operative funds and savings banks and only few loans from individuals. On i July 19x2 Tak- kula and Niptili colonies were most indebted to banks, their debts of this description averaging 130, increased from 57 Finnish marks, for a lot. The increase of indebtedness to banks in Nippuli is to be ascribed to the fact that nine colonists became burdened with a debt of 4,000 Finnish marks as a result of fraudulent discounting, and implicated their property in conse- quence. Loans from private persons are very considerable in the colonies of Muddais (average yearly increase of 117 Finnish marks a lot), Seppala (of 78 Finnish marks), Takkula (of 43 Finnish marks) and Nipuli (of 39 Finnish marks). 3. Current debts. The author reckons among these debts such as have a more accidental character and do not bear interest. Such is the credit which the country tradespeople afford for goods ordered by the colonists. These debts were relatively very great in Nipuli colony where their annual increase averaged 2S6 Finnish marks a lot. The average annual increase in current debts among all the lots investigated was 30 Finnish marks per lot or 2.80 Finnish marks per hectare of cultivated land. 3. Debts incurred to the forests. Since it was the aim of the whole en- quiry to discover the action on agriculture only of such capital as was in- THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 103 vested in farming, the forest dues were reckoned among the liabiHties the colonists incurred b}^ forestry, as against the uses they made of their wood- land possessions. The total value of the forest dues from the time the land was taken over until the close of the period of enquiry was 52,434 Finnish marks. The yearly average for a lot was 138 Finnish marks, or for a hectare of cul- tivated land 13.05 Finish marks. From the total sum of the forest dues 79.7 per cent, must be deducted as the value of the woodland products (fuel) and 20.3 per cent, as that of pasturage. The firewood used on the farms is for the most part gathered from the fallen wood, and wood having a market value is seldom used as fuel. In Muddais, where there is less woodland than in the other colonies, the colonists take firewood from their wood most sparingly. It has happened that firewood has been sold by the colonists outside a colony, being transported by water. In Takkula the colonists procure their firewood from distant forests and therefore are very careful in their use of it. The costs of importing wood are a considerable burden on the farming of the colonists. The yearly value of the woodland pasturage in the different colonies for single lots is computed by the author as follows : Muddais Sippola Siikajarvi Nipuli Koskipaa Takkula Seppala Average for a lot Houses Finnish marks 12 I 3 Cows Finnish marks 22 16 16 24 39 12 9 Sheep Finnish marks The sum of inheritances and presents received by the colonists during the time of the enquiry was 5,687 Finnish marks, an average of 67 Finnish marks for a lot or 6.27 for a hectare of land. § 7. Changes in assets and liapilities and t?ie net profit m.\de. The two preceding sections have given the alterations in the single as- sets and liabilities and the groups of these. We will now resume and com- pare all assets and liabilities as they were both before and after the lots were 104 RUSSIA - AGRICULTUKAl, ECONOMY IN GENKKAL taken over and at the close of the period of enquiry. The net profit will then appear. For whole area. Before lands were taken over . . . After » » » » . . . On I July 1 91 2 Average for i lot. Before lands were taken over . . . After » » » » . . . On I July 1 91 2 Average for i hectare cultivated land. Before lands were taken over . . . After » » » «... On I July 1912 Assets Liabilities Net profits innisb marks Finnish marks Finnish marks 176,060 11,055 165,005 350,296 185,291 165,005 644.235 281,051 366,184 2,071 130 1. 941 4,120 2,179 1,941 7,614 3,306 4,308 203.22 1307 195-15 414.41 219.26 195-15 712.89 309.50 403-39 From this it appears that assets, liabilities and net profits were notably increased during the period of enquiry. The relative values of single assets and their alteration can be seen from the following figures ; Before After lands were taken over lands were taken over I July 1912 Farming Household Secondary businesses .... Personal possessions Debts recoverable by colonists Total . . 60.9 % 3.2 % 19.6 % 16.3 % 100 % 80.3 % 1.6 o/^ 9-9 % 8.2 o/„ 100 o/^ 86.6 % 1-4 % 1.6 % 5.1 % 5.3 % 100 % The largest part of this property was thus bound up with farming and its proportion to the whole capital invested increased from 60.9 per cent. before the land was taken over to 86.6 per cent, on i July igi2. In the individual colonies the course of this process was various, ac- cording to whether before the lots were taken over there were already farms on their sites or not. In Koskipaa, Nipuli and Siikajarvi the colonists found small farms ready-made at the time of colonization, and therefore the farming capital in these places was already considerable before the land was taken over. The same holds good for Seppala colony where most of the colonists were previously torpars. Conditions were different in the colo- nies of Muddais, Sippola and Takkula where, before the land was taken THE RESUIvTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 105 over, the capital invested in secondary businesses was most important. After the lots had been taken over the class of capital previously domi- nant continued to form a high percentage of the whole value involved, yet the distribution of the components of capital tended to be somewhat equalized in the different colonies, except in Seppala colony where at the close of the enquiry the farming capital was in distinctly higher proportion than in the others. The following table makes these facts clear : Proportionate Distrihution of Component Parts of Capital invested in the Colonies. Components of Capital Sippola Sii- kajarvi Nipuli Kos- kipaa Seppala Before land was taken over Farming Household Secondary businesses. . Personal belongings . . Forestry etc 411% 2-6% 38.1 % 18.2 o/„ 54-7% 3-4 % 24.6 % 17-3 % 71.6 % 74.3 % 5.1% 3-8% (>-9 % 16.4 % 6.5 % 15.4 % 78.6 % 3.7% 6.2 % 11-5% 60.5 % 2-3% 17-6% 19.6 % 76.1 % 2.8% 9.1 % 12.0% Average for i lot in Finnish marks 100% 2,679 100 % 2,781 957 100 % 1.309 100 % 100% 100 % 2,908 2,450 1,380 After land was taken over: Farming Household Secondary businesses Personal belongings Forestiy etc 693 % 1-3% 19.9 % 9.5 % 76.3 % 1-8% 12.9% 9-0 % 84-9 % 2.7 % 3-7% 8.7 % 86.3 % 2.0 % 3-5 % 8.2 o/^ 87-6 % 2.2 0/0 3.6% 6.6 <^x 78.1% 1-3 % 9-8 % 10.8 % 94-0 % o-7% 2.3 % 3.0% Average for i lot in Finnish marks )o % 100 % 100 % ,132 5.305 1,794 100 % ' 100 % 100 % 2,457 5,050 4.405 On I July 191 2 Farming Household Secondary businesses Personal belongings . Forestry etc. .... 87-1% 1-7 % i-i % 5.9% 4-2 % 87-4% 1-4% 2.5% 5.8 % 2.9% 86.9 % 1-5% o.S <% 4-7% 6.1 % 87.8 % 1-3 % 0.1 % 5.3 % 5.5i% 100 % 5,470 8i.o:% 0.8 o^ 4.0% 13.0% 83.8 % 1.6% 4-7 % 6.4 % 3.5 % 92.6 o/q 1.2% 0.4 % 3-7% 2.1 % Average for i lot in Finnish marks 100 % 8,386 100 % 8,607 100 % 100 % 4,269 3,994 100 % 10.545 100 % 8,926 100 % 12,168 io6 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAI. ECONOMY IN GENERAI, For the purpose of a comparison with these figures the author gives also data as to the total assets of Siberian colonists. In Popov (i) these averaged in the colonists' lots investigated by him 1,365 roubles (2) a lot, distributed as follows : Cattle and poultry Farming implements, carts etc. . . Buildings Clothes Crockery and furniture, Total 387 roubles 322 316 286 54 i;365 28.4 % 23-6 % 23-1 % 21.0 % 3.9 % 100 % The average percentage of the Habihties in the lots investigated was as follows : When lots were taken over After they had been taken over 1 July 1912 Debt on the land Other debts bearing interest . . Current debts Percent. 73-1 26.9 Percent. 94.0 4-3 1-7 Percent. 6C.3 14.9 4.1 20.7 Use of woodland. ....... 100 100 ICG Thus when the land was taken over debts to savings banks and pri- vate persons predominated. After it had been taken over these items be- came, as compared with the debt on the land, almost negligible, but on I July 1912 were quite noticeable. The debt on the land although at first, as we have already said, there was no obUgation on the colonists to make an- nual payments towards redeeming it, sank from 94 per cent, to 60.3 per cent, of the total sum of the liabilities. The oscillations of these liabilities in the single colonies appear in the following table : (i) Angaben iiber die budget-wirtschaftliche Untersuchung von 75 Vbcrsicdlermrtschaften in den Kreisen Kustanaisk, Aktjnbinsk und Uralsk. Orenburg, 191 1, pp. 10 et seq. {2) I rouble = about 2s. ^Vod. at par. THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND 107 Relative Percentage of Chief Liabilities of Different Colonies. Liabilities Muddais Sippola Sii- kajarvi Nipuli Kos- kipaa Takkula Seppala Before lands were taken over: Debt on land Debts bearing interest 59.0 41.0 30-5 69.5 44-4 55-6 99-9 0.1 ICO 100 100 Forest dues etc — Average for i lot in Finnish marks 100 144 100 121 100 187 100 123 100 ID ICO 89 100 262 A fter lands were taken over : Debt on land Debts bearing interest Current debts 94-5 3-2 2.3 95-5 1.4 3-1 81.7 8.1 10.2 90.3 9.6 0.1 99-5 0-5 95-6 4-4 94-0 6.0 Forest dues etc — . Average for i lot in Finnish marks 100 2,597 100 2,645 100 1,025 100 1,271 100 2,152 100 2,044 100 4,352 I July 1912 ; Debt on land Debts bearing interest Current debts Forest dues etc 66.4 17.8 0-5 15.3 72.5 5-7 6.8 15.0 39-3 10.2 I3-I 37-4 50-9 19-3 12.5 17-3 53-4 9.9 36.7 53.8 28.8 17-^ 69.1 II. 6 19.3 Average for i lot in Finnish marks 100 3,552 100 3,472 100 2,196 100 2,297 100 3,478 100 3,521 100 5.853 Altogether assets have on an average increa,sed by 84.8 per cent, of the vakte of the capital when the land was taken over, and liabilities by only 51.7 per cent. When the land was taken over the liabilities amounted to 52.9 per cent, of the total capital and on i July 1912 to 43.4 per cent. The debts have increased relatively onl}^ in Nipuli colony, namely from 51.8 per cent, to 57.5 per cent. Yet even here there was an increase of net profit. The increase of debts was to that of assets in the ratio of 32.3 to 100. For one hectare of cultivated land the average increase of assets is valued at 298. 48 Finnish marks, that of liabilities at 90.27 Finnish marks. io8 RUSSIA - AGRICUIvTURAIv ECONOMY IN GENERAL As the size of the farms increases so does the amount of both the as- sets and the habihties, yet if the average for one hectare of cultivated land be calculated it is found that both decrease with the size of the farms. The yearly increase of assets and liabilities in the single colonies ap- pears from the following figures : In Seppala yearly increase Sippola " Takkula Muddais Siikajarvi Koskipaa " Nipuh Average assets for a lot. of 1,252 Q87 847 751 741 665 455 Finnish marks Average liabilities for a lot. In Siikajarvi yearly increase of ISiipuli Seppala Takkula Sippola Muddais Koskipaa 349 306 281 277 247 220 162 Additional figures will answer a question which has great interest for the whole enquiry. What was the colonists' net profit from the time the lots were taken over until i July igi2 ? The difference between the assets and liabilities gives this information: In Seppala yearly increase of 971 Finnish marks, i. e. 5.33 » Sippola i> » » 740 » 3-33 .1 Takkula » » » 570 " .5-33 » Muddais » " 531 » 4-33 » Koskipaa >, • » 503 » 8.17 » Siikajarvi „ » 392 » 3-33 ■■< Nipuli » » 149 " 3-33 This order is almost exactly that in which the colonies stood to each other in respect of their assets ; except that Siikajarvi and Koskipaa co- lonies have changed places, the former from the fifth to the sixth place, the latter from the sixth to the fifth. It is also interesting to establish the number of the colonists as com- pared with the increase in net profits, classified according to its extent, when the land was taker over and on i July 191 2 : THE RESUI 1) 5,000 11 6,000 11 !) 11 6,000 11 7,000 » 11 11 7,000 » 8,000 11 11 u 8,000 >' 9,000 11 11 » 9,000 11 10,000 ■■> 11 10,000 and more » » 8 21 15 12 7 6 3 9 4 312 735 1,245 1.735 2,328 2,705 3.239 4.489 6,234 3 3 9 8 6 8 8 10 ^ 7 2 6 I 5 366 833 1,233 1.826 2,237 2,810 3,651 4.381 5,599 6,337 7.404 8,469 9,368 11,640 Average . . . 85 1.941 85 4.308 From this table it appears that the large number of colonists whose net profits when the land was taken over were between 500 and 2000 Finnish marks, was notably increased before the close of the enquiry. The colo- nists having net profits between 2000 and 6000 Finnish marks also became more numerous, in spite of the number whose profits came to be from 6,000 to 10,000 Finnish marks and more. § 8. Interest, Wx\ges of i^abour and wages of enterprise. After he has shown the total results of the colonists' farming and the total increase of their propert5^ the author seeks to describe the origin and constitution of this increase. As has been stated several times the ground rent is not included in the net profits of the colonists as here established by the author. The net profits have three constituents : interest on the capi- tal invested in the farm, wages for the colonists' agricultural labour and wa- ges for their enterprise. As to the last two of these constituents it has been impossible to de- termine them because there are no data from bookkeeping and calculable 8* no RUSSIA - AGRICUI,TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL facts as to the part taken by the colonist families in the work on and outside the farms, and the returns of the farms to the families. It has been possible to calculate only the interest on the capital invested in the farms. As the result of the enquiry into the net profits of the 85 lots the>' have been, from this point of view, classified in three groups. The first group includes five colonists' farms which have suffered a reduction of capital : namely two in Muddais where such reduction has been of I per cent, and 4 per cent. , and three in Nipuli where it has been of 2 per cent., 6 per cent, and 34 per cent. The second group includes two farms which show at most a net profit of 5 per cent, on the capital invested in them. They are a colonLst' s lot in Nipuli and one in Koskipaa on which the yearly increase is 2 per cent, of the capital. The third group comprises 78 farms of which the capital has increased animalh'' by 5 per cent, or more of its amount. In this group the colonists' farms have made a return not only of such 5 per cent, interest on capital but also of a surplus, distributed among the lots as follows : Number of lots Amount of surplus calculated for a lot Average 27 CJp to 200 Finnish marks 115 Finnish marks 20 From 200 » 400 » » 318 » » 12 » 400 » 600 1) » 511 » » 9 » 600 » 800 » » 710 » » 7 » 800 » 1,000 » » 915 » 3 » 1,000 and more » » 1,088 " » If the proportions obtaining within single colonies be studied the sur- plus, after 5 per cent, interest on capital has been deducted, is found to be as follows : Name of Colony Amount of surplus on a lot Average for i lot Niptdi Koskipaa Siikajarvi Takkula Muddais Sippola Seppala Average for whole area 15 'o 358 Finnish marks 77 » 714 » 82 » 550 » » 23 » 937 » » 43 » 1,101 » 74 " 1.070 » » 472 i> 1,094 " " 15 to 1,101 Finnish marks 84 Finnish marks 284 314 396 » 407 565 783 355 Finnish marks THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND III The animal gross profits of the colonists' farms are employed as follows : i) the colonists' families have their livelihoods ; 2) they discharge their liabilities ; 3) they receive 5 per cent, interest on the capital invested in the farm, household and secondary businesses as well as 4) a yearly surplus averaging 355 Finnish marks for a lot. * * * The author also endeavours to bring the amount of the net profits, as these vary with time, into relation with the factors influencing the farming of colonists, in order thus to establish a certain relation of cause and effect between these factors and the increase in the value of the property. General conclusions cannot here be drawn because the material for research and the data derived from bookkeeping are relatively too slight. It has been possible to discover only a tendency and to offer a cursory introduction to later studies. Next the size of the lots is considered, and the absolute conclusion is at once made that the yearly increase in net profits rises with an extension in the area of the farms. But the development shows a tendency to an equal- ization of net profits with the original net profits of the time when the land was taken over. If taken absolutely the original net profits are directly related to the yearly increase : the greater thej^ are, by so much the greater are the yearty net profits. If taken relative^ the increase is found to be greater in farms which had at first little value. The available labour power in colonists' families has not notably influenced either absolutely or relatively the yearly increase in net profits. If the family be large it uses a proportionately large amount of the farm products, and various of its members must find exterior employment which seldom offers opportunities for saving. The amount of consumption and the available labour power of the families have however influenced the an- nual increase of net profits in the sense that the latter is proportionate to consumption. This relation, the connection between the growing value of the propert}' and the needs it supplies, cannot be explained by the ma- terial of the enquir}^ The relation of the net profits to thedift'erent origins of single colonists' farms is shown as follows. The highest annual increase in value, absokite and relative, occurs in farms established on former sites of the dwellings of cottagers and labourers. Next come such farms as stand on laud previously cultivated but having had no buildings ; thirdly the farms formed on land which had not been cultivated previous!}^ ; and lastly those on the sites of the labourers' leaseholds, the earlier torps, which show the least increase in annual profits. Here also no general conclusions can be made ; first because the num- ber of the inve.stigated lots is too small ; and secondly because the effects 1 12 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAI. ECONOMY IX GENERAL of this factor of the origins of the farms is influenced — strengthened or weakened — by other forces. Thus most of the torps — 31 of them alto- gether — lie in the colonies in which farming is at its weakest, namely in Nipuli and Koskipaa. The circumstance is nevertheless noteworthy that the yearly increase in value of the farms on the entirely new sites is higher than that of those occu])ying the sites of torps. Conclusion. We will now briefly resume all that is contained in the foregoing para graphs. The enquiry into the lots colonized by peasant smallholders has very indubitabl}^ given the information that the colonizing enterprise of the State has been crowned with success. Bj' the institution of an especial credit fund for the landless population, by furnishing the colonists with cheap land credit, by the formation of a lease office, and by enlisting the aid of co-operation for the purpose of acquiring land, colonizing enterprise has succeeded in strengthening the position of the colonists as farmers of the lots they have acquired, in providing them with a sure livelihood, and in attach- ing them to their native soil. The happiness which once they sought over seas, which once called them to America, that belauded country, they now find more easily within their own land. Naturally much energy, activity and intense industry is demanded of the colonists : but nowhere can a man advance himself if he keep his hands in his pockets ; and from the social point of view the efforts which colonists nmst make on the land are certainly not more injurious to them than those incumbent on workers in factories and State industries. There must be economy, every step forward must be accomipanied by economical housekeeping, if the deve- lopment of a colonist's lot is to be at all reasonably profitable. But the awakening of an agricultural sense, the education in thrift especially of the unendowed populace — these constitute, as the author observes, so lofty, so important and so educational an aim, that it alone gives great significance to colonizing enterprise. When the new State colonizing enterprise in Finland was initiated Profes.sor Hamer Gebhard (i), the well-known creator of the P'innish co-operative movement, wrote as follows : " There are too many families in Finland who own neither land nor house. There are at the same time vast extents of uncultivated territory of which part might be cultivated... It behoves that with the help of capital these two factors, the man and the land, be united : the result will be for (i) Atlas df statistique socialc sur Ics communes rurales dc Finlandc en igoi. Hel- singfors, 1908. p. 57. THE RESULTS OF INTERIOR COLONIZATION IN FINLAND II3 Finland such hitherto unsuspected strength and new wealth as will contri- bute to making a better future for the country. It should be mentioned that the government and the representatives of the nation have taken this problem seriously, and they will doubtless find for it in the near future a happy solution ". It is with satisfaction that we can state that this prophec}' already begins to be fulfilled and that colonizing activity has already borne good fruit. It has led, as we have seen, to a progressive development of the property of the colonists, and in so doing has indicated the lines which the colonizing policy of Finland should follow in the future. SERBIA. THE QUESTION OF FORESTRY IN THE KINGDOM OF SERBIA, OFFICIAI, SOURCES : CTaTiiCTiirKii roAiiiiiH>aK sa 1907/8 {Statistical Yearbook for 1907-8). Belgrade, 1913. Hapo^Ha IIpiiBpe/i;a y Hpircajej];Hr£>eHHM06jiaCTnMa {National Economy in the New Territory). Belgrade, 1914. OTHER SOURCES : Vasic D. E. M) : La sylviculture en Serbie {Sylviculture in Serbia). Belgrade, 1911. lovANovic (D. G. S.) : Oahoch H3Mery npiipofle ti iiiyMa y Kpat.eBirHit Cp6HJH {Nature and the Woods in the Kingdom of Serbia). Belgrade, 1903. Vasic (D. M. S.) : Hauie niyMe (The Serbian Woods). Belgrade, 1904. Vasic (D. M. S.) : IIIyMe y Tapn {The Wood of « Ta!a«). Belgrade, 1908. Vasic (A. M. S.) : OvKaiiiiraBibe niyMa y Cp6iiJH {The Delimitation of the Woods in Seibia). Belgrade, 1909. Before examining the condition of sylviculture in the kingdom of Serbia it is necessary to note the two following facts : 1) Sylviculture in Old ySerbia, that is within the land of the kingdom as it existed before the Balkan Wars, differs somewhat from sylviculture in the recently occupied country in respect of the wooded territory, the quality of the timber and the method of cultivating it. 2) All statistical data as to sylviculture in Old and in New Serbia have not the same value. Some are certainly ver}' precise and very detailed, but others are summary and approximate. Those which relate to the extent and the quality of the woods in Old Serbia are precise, for there the departmental administrative body care- fully drew up the cadaster with a view to ascertaining these points ; but the data relating to the ownership of the woodlands should be considered as approximate and only partially exact. The commissions, which are called Commissions of Delimitation and were formed for the express pur- pose of determining on the ancient territory the limits of the properties of the State, the communes and individuals, have not yet brought the la- bours of the cadaster to an end everywhere, although they have existed for twenty-five years, and dependable statistical data are available onh' for the woodlands in which they have completed their task. THE QUESTION OF FORESTRY II5 As regards the utilization of the woods in Old Serbia there are exact data only for the domanial forests. Those for the forests in private owner- ship are no more than approximately accurate. Only summary data are available as to sylviculture in the recently occupied territory. Immediately after the occupation a commission was nominated to study sylviculture in the new territory. The departmental forest administrations, formed at the same time, were charged with the preparation of a pro\dsional cadaster. The reports of this commission and these administrative bodies contain data as to the condition of sylvicul- ture in the new territor}^ but having been collected in only one year they cannot be more than summary and approximately accurate. § I. Extent of woodlands and varieties of timber. Old Serbia. — Old Serbia has an area of 4,830,260 hectares (i). Of this the woods occupy 1,517,000 hectares, that is 31.4 per cent., and they comprise every species of tree which grows in Central Europe but espe- cially beeches, oaks, Scotch and spruce firs and juniper-trees. Beeches occupy 60 per cent, of all the woodland and are most numerous in the north. The fir woods which cover only 12 per cent, of the territory are most frequently found in the west (departments of Uzice, Ciacik and Kruscievaz) . The oak woods form 23 per cent, of the woodland and are in the south (departments of Kruscievaz, Nish and Toplitza). This distri- bution is however not absolute but comparative : all the species enumera- ted may be said to exist all over the country. More than half the woodlands — 60 per cent. — is formed of mixed trees. There are woods of beeches and oaks, and of oaks, beeches and firs. Only 40 per cent, of the woodlands consist of trees of a single kind. All the woods of Old Serbia are mature and ready to be cut. The most imi)ortant wooded zones are the following : i) In the east : a) Miroci, a beach wood of 27,000 hectares : h) Deli-Jovan, a beech wood of 7,000 hectares ; c) The wooded territory between the Porecika and the Danube and between the lines joining the towns of Golubaz, Despotovatz and Bol- jevatz, all beech wood and extending over 120,000 hectares. 2) In the west : a) Maljen, a wood of beeches, oaks and firs having an area of 20,000 hectares ; b) Bozania, a wood of 15,000 hectares, of beeches and oaks ; c) Tara, a fir wood of about 25,000 hectares. 3) In the south-west : a) Gocz, a wood of mixed firs on the slope and of beeches and oaks, having an area of more than 20,000 hectares. (i) 1 hectare == 2 acres i rood 35.383 poles. II 6 SERBIA - AGRICUI^TURAI. ECONOMY IN GENERAL b) Golija, Cemerono and Copoanic woods, which occupy together 70,000 hectares and are of mixed firs and oaks. 4) In the sonth-east : Jastrebaz, TopHza, Kukaviza, Suva Planina and Stara Planina, woods of mixed oaks and beeches which have a combined area of 130,000 hectares. New Serbia. — New Serbia has an area of 3,800,000 hectares, of which 570,000 hectares or 15 per cent, are wooded. It should be noted that in a period which is not yet very remote New Serbia. was extremely rich in woods. During the last ten or fifteen years they have'^been burnt and destroyed by private persons and by govern- ment agents, by the former in order to gain pasturage for live stock and by the latter in order better to get rid of the comitadjis who infested the country-. The commission nominated b}^ the vSerbian government, to study the condition of sylviculture in New Serbia, has established that 22,800,000 hectares — that is 60 per cent, of the woodland — are fitted exclusively for sylviculture which might become a verj' lucrative branch of industry. The commission has proposed that all this land be reforested. In respect of the quality of the timber New Serbia is like Old Serbia : the same trees are found although in slightly different proportions. In New Serbia the beech and oak woods are most numerous. They cover almost equal areas and constitute together 80 per cent, of the wood- land. The fir woods occupy only 15 per cent and are met with most fre- quently in the south (woods of Morihovo, Marijano and Malesc). Most of the woods are mixed (woods of beeches and oaks, woods of firs and beeches). Woods of a single species of tree are very rare (Zlabar, Garvan, Korituic and the mountainous summits of Morihovo and Marijano) The most important wooded zones are the following : i) In the north : a) Zlatar, a fir wood having an area between 6,000 and 7,000 hectares ; b) Jarut, a wood of beeches and oaks, having an area between 4,000 and 5,000 hectares ; c) Slona Gora, a fir wood of from 3,000 to 4,000 hectares ; d) Rogosma, a wood of oaks and beeches of from 12,000 to 15,000 hectares ; e) Copaonic, a wood of oaks and beeches — 15,000 to 20,000 hectares ; f) Ciciaviza, a wood of beeches and oaks of 10,000 hectares. g) Prapastiza, oaks and beeches — 12,000 to 15,000 hectares. 2) In the east : a) Lisaz, a wood of beeches and oaks of from 4,000 to 5,000 hectares ; b) Placiacavita. a wood of oaks and beeches of from 15,000 to 16,000 hectares ; c) Garvan and Goben, woods of beeches and oaks having a combined area of from 6,000 to 8,000 hectares. THE QUESTION OF FORESTRY II7 3) In the south : a) Marijansca Planina, a wood of firs with beeches and oaks on the slope, of from 10,000 to 12,000 hectares ; b) Morihovo, a fir wood of 15,000 hectares ; c) Petrinske Planina, a wood of oaks and beeches of from 6,000 to 8,000 hectares ; d) Baba and Buscieva Planina, a wood of beeches and oaks of from 5,000 to 6,000 hectares. 4) In the west : a) Zegavaz, a wood of beeches and oaks of from 8,000 to 10,000 hectares ; b) Caradaj, a beech wood of from 8,000 to 10,000 hectares; c) Milanovaz, a wood of beeches and oaks of 10,000 hectares ; d) Blet, a wood of beeches and oaks of from 6,000 to 8,000 hectares. § 2. The ownership of the woods. Old Serbia. — As has already been said Commissions of DeUmita- tion, charged to determine property rights in the woodlands, were fovmded by the law of 1891, that is twenty-five years ago. They began work in 1892 ; but their activity was limited to two or three months a year — July, August and September — and as it has not yet come to an end the ownership of many woods is still uncertain. It follows that the relevant statistical data are exact only for the woods in which the delimitation has been executed and approximate for all the others. Most of the woods belong to the State and the communes. The State's property has an area of 620,000 hectares, that of the communes 580,000 hectares. The remaining woods belong to churches and convents as to 60,000 hectares and to private persons as to 257,000 hectares. Nei& Serbia. — Statistical data as to property rights in the wood- lands are entirely lacking for this territory'. The commission charged to study the condition of sylviculture there neglected the question of owner- ship, for this is connected with the agrarian question which is the object of an enquiry by another commission. Property in land in New vSerbia has retained features characteristic of the feudal regime, and these are found in the woodlands. The typical forms of landed property in New Serbia are the following : i) Domain — that is the property of the State, administered and en- joyed by the State directly. 2) Mefat -— the property of the State of which the use is left pubHc. 3) Baltalic — the property of the communes. It is always doubtful whether the communes are owners in fact, or are merely usufructories of land jurisdictorily owned by the State. 4) Vakouf — the property of churchers and convents. In the case of these also there is doubt as to whether the churches and convents are true owners or merelv usufructories. Il8 SERBIA - AGRTCUI.TURAI, ECONOMY IX GENERAL 5) Coria — private propert}'. Coria is found in three different forms : a) Property in the true sense of the word, based on a legal title. b) Property resultant on usufruct, that is the property of a usufruc- tor>' of the State who declares himself owner. c) Detention following on illegitimate occupation of lands belonging to the State or the communes (Mefat, Baltalic), the detainer having, after some years, declared himself owner. The proportion in which these various kinds of ownership, of usufruct and of possession as the result of prolonged occupation exist, is unknown. § 3. The utilization of the woods. Old Serbia. — Until 1891, that is until the new law as to the woods was voted, it may be said that profit was derived from them by means of thefts of wood. In the communal woods felling, which was effected without any State intervention, was considered to be the incontestable right of all indivi- duals belonging to the commune. The mayor gave formal leave for it as need arose. The leave specified only the number of trees which might be cut down : their choice was left to individual discretion. For tree-felling in State woods special leave from government officials was necessar3^ It was allowed freely on the sole condition that the timber should be used for the feller or his famil}^ if he were recognized to be poor ; otherwise he had to pay a small due. In the form granting permission to cut down trees belonging to the State the number which might be felled was indicated. There was no restriction on choice. It is not astonishing that this method of administering the woods caused their progressive disappearance, but the destruction was less than might be supposed. The smallness of the population and the lack of means of transport were obstacles to this unscientific employment of the woods. The law of 1891 put a stop to it and gave a better basis to the uti- lization of woods. According to the rules laid down b}^ this law the State woods can be utiHzed only on the following conditions : i) Before felling is allowed a scheme for it is drawn up b\' the Forest Administration . 2) The form giving permission to cut down trees not only specifies the number which may be cut down but also the condition that none ma}' be felled except such as are indicated by the competent Forest Admin- istration. 3) Tree-felling for a commercial or industrial object and on a large scale cannot be effected without reforestation, for which a scheme is drawn up b}' the administration. THE QUESTION OF FORESTRY IIQ 4) The use of mountain pasturages and the utihzation of acorns are limited as to season and area. The Forest Administration fixes the parti- cular woodland and the time — that is when and where the animals may graze. In addition to these rules, determining the utilization of the State woods, the law of 1891 is concerned with the communal woods and those in private ownership. Felling in communal woods is conditioned as in State woods. In woods in private ownership the conditions are a little less strict but in these also only trees indicated by the competent Forest Administration may be felled. * * * The official statistics distinguish between wood cutting of three kinds : i) w^oodcutiing for firewood ; 2) woodcutting for domestic uses ; 3) woodcutting for commercial and industrial objects. By woodcutting] for firewood is meant only the cutting done by the peasants, to obtain wood winch they or their families burn or which they sell in the towns in small quantities. By woodcutting for domestic uses cutting done by peasants is also meant, in this case in order that they may make furniture or utensils or parts of agricultural tools (§ 46-50) (i). Woodcutting for commercial and industrial objects comprises : a) Such felling of large quantities of timber as is habitual to mer- chants. b) The woodcutting of industrial workers and labourers whose material is wood. c) Woodcutting by merchants dealing in wood. Woodcutting for firewood and domestic uses and woodcutting by workmen whose material is wood occur in all the departments, in the State woods as in the communal woods and in those in private ownership. Woodcutting by merchants dealing in wood takes place especially in the departments of Golubaz and Alessinaz where more than 80 per cent, of the timber felled altogether in Old Serbia is cut down. Woodcutting for purposes of industry and by merchants dealing in wood takes place in the departments of Baina Bascta, Uzize, Pascka, Kral- jevo, Procuplje, Kruscevaz and Pirot. In Prouplje and Kruscevaz oak- wood is cut down, in all the others firwood. Both kinds of felling take place almost exclusively in the State woods ; such felling in the communal and private woods is quite negligible. (i) While natural economy was in foice woodcutting for domestic uses had a great importance which however is now diminishing more and more. 120 SERBIA - AGRICUIvTURAI. ECONOMY IN GENERAL We show the amount of timber of the different categories derived from the felHngs of 1911 : 73,651 cubic metres (i) 17,020 » )) 120,000 1. Woodcutting for firewood 2. )) )) domestic uses. . . . 3. » » commercial and in- dustrial purposes : a) woodcutting for firewood .... » by merchants, in- dustrial workers and workmen whose material is wood 310,000 » « 520,680 » » Woodcutting for firewood and for the material of industry has met all the needs of the country in these respects. The foreign trade in firewood and wood as material was at first unim- portant, but latterly there has been a change. While in the past Serbia imported all her luxurious furniture from abroad, she has in recent years begun to export her wood and her imports of furniture have diminished more and more. The following table gives data as to the export and import of wood. Import Export Firewood Wood as material 1908 1909 1910 19H I912 45.580 195,686 164,341 340,936 "3,335 473,395 375,984 329,498 536,184 507,122 395,355 269,751 260,009 1,033,051 839,318 134,829 11,569,254 137,962 I 246,691 145,360 450,280 166,368 255,413 184,950 389,415 1,229,893 1,214,835 956,340 422,245 999,416 Pasturage in the woods and the utilization of acorns are enjoyed on a large scale but the relevant statistics are known only as to the State woods. For 1915 they are as follows : (i) I cubic metre = 1.308 cubic y;'.id~. THE QUESTION OF FORESTRY 121 Pastured sheep 157.336 V cattle 21,786 >> goats 13.438 » horses 2,680 » pigs 6,550 in addition to 23,583 pigs'fed on acorns (i). New Serbia. — The utihzation of the woods of New vSerbia consisted fundamentally, as in old Serbia, in the theft of wood. It has been said that the large woods were burnt and destroyed. This was done : i) By the " cipcije ", the land serfs, who, since the}' held no land and cultivated the land . of feudatories under the obhgation of pa3'ing feudal dues, set fire to these woods in order to obtain new pasturage for their live stock, the keeping of which — since live stock were free from taxes — was their most lucrative form of activit^^ 2) By government agents who burnt the woods in order that they might not shelter comitadjis. In the period of Turkish domination the government and the private woods were regularlj- utilized, but most unscientifically and without the exercise of any guardianship on the part of the State. So much was this the case that leave to cut wood in the government woods was obtained easily : b^- pa^'ing a very small due one might cut down at one's own dis- cretion as much as one chose. As for private woods the vState con- cerned itself not at all with them : the wood was cut at the full and abso- lute discretion of the owners. Woodcutting was at this time undertaken to procure : a) firewood, h) green branches for feeding live stock, c) various kinds of wood. Woodcutting for the two first of these objects was by itself very im- portant ; that for the third was quite negligible. In all New Serbia there were in this period only two saw-works, namely in the wood of Ozany which belonged to the convent of St. Troiza and in the wood of Maistorsca Tora which belonged to the manufacturer and mer- chant Necib Draga. It is probable that the pasturage in the woods was very important, but no data allow a precise idea of it to be formed. § 4. Forest administration. The ancient territory of the kingdom of Serbia is divided into twenty- four forest districts, each of which has its particular administration. (i) The utilization of the acorns in the woods has been very imporlanl in the last twenty years during which the meat of the pigs called « paloziie » has been much exported, but such exportation is diminishing piogressively. 122 SERBIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Kach district administration comprises a cliief administrator who is at its head, several subordinate administrators and a suitable number of keepers. The chief administrator must have studied in a secondary' and the subordinate administrators in a secondary or primary school of forestr}', while the keepers must have followed simple courses of instruc- tion in forestry. As there are no schools in Serbia for this branch of know- ledge the administrators, both chief and subordinate, must have studied abroad ; but the courses of instruction in forestry for the keepers take place in Belgrade. The central forest administration is part of the Ministry of Agricul- ture, Industr3' and Commerce, forming that one of its five sections which is called the forestry section. This has economic and jurisdictory^ divisions, of which the former directs the forest policy of the country, while the latter has charge of the delimitation of forest landed property' and of summonses to appear in cases of contravention of the law in matters pe^ taining to forests. * * * If we study sylviculture in vSerbia with any depth we perceive its two principal defects : i) The division into forest departments, that is into forest departmen- tal administrations, is inadequate. The departments are too vast : it is impossible for the administrator to superintend and control forestry within one of them and to adopt opportune measures in good time. This division must therefore be completely recast, less extent must be given to the departments, and the staff employed in each of them must be increased. 2) Reforestation, which has certainly been somewhat neglected, should be the object of more care. We have stated that the woods of New Serbia occupy only 15 per cent, of the total area while more than 60 per cent, is fitted for sy-lviculture. It is therefore necessary to reforest if not all the extent of territory admitting of reforestation at least a considerable part of it. In OldvSerbia, where the woods occupy 31.4 per cent, of the total area, the problem is easier to solve : the matter is merely one of building up the woods in proportion to the amount of tree-felling done. The law makes reforestation compulsory only in the case of felling for a commercial or in- dustrial object All other felling, whatever its object, has the effect of thinning the woods. It is therefore absolutely necessary to render refor- estation compulsory in every case, and in every wood, whether public or private. MISCEIvIvANEOUS INFORMATION REI.ATING TO AGRICUIvTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAI, IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. ARGENTINE REPUBLIC. FORMATION OF AGRICUI^TURAI, COI^ONIKS FOR THE INDIANS. — Boldin oficial, Buenos Ayres, Number 6764, 9 August 1916. The incorporation of the native population in civil life has for long constantly preoccu])ied the Argentine government, on account both of its social and of its economic advantages. Recent decrees have attempted, within the limits allowed b}'' the laws now in force, not only to solve the problem for the native groups in the south of the republic but also to form colonies which aim especially at giving a stable position to the Indians of the north. As a consequence of colonizing necessities this undertaking has become particularly urgent, and a proposed law, submitted to the congress, aims at protecting the Indians from the manoeuvres of unscrupulous merchants and at encouraging their definite establishment in certain zones appro- priated to them. Pending the voting of this law however administrative measures have been taken to obtain the same result immediately. Among them is the decree of 26 July 1916 which forms for the Tobas and Pilagaes Indians two colonies for arable and live stock farming. Numerous groups of these natives have expressed their desire to bene- fit by the arrangements made for the Indian tribes and to establish them- selves at certain points of the Chaco and Formosa territory which they occupy already. After an enquiry made by government officials, which ascertained that these lands were appropriated to agriculture, two colo- nies for arable and live stock farming were formed, one in Chaco having an area of some 53,000 hectares (i), and the other reaching on the south to the Rio Pilcomayo and comprising about 85,000 hectares. A new step has thus been taken towards the civilization of these tribes: they abandon the nomad state and agree to establish themselves in a fixed place and give themselves uj) to the work of agriculture. (i) hectare = 2 acres 1 rood 35.383 jjoles. 124 INFORMATION REI,ATING TO AGRICCI.TURAI. ECONOMY IN GENERAL AUSTRALIA. CLOSER SETTLE:VIENT. — Dalgety's Review. Sydney, July 1916. One very material effect of the war has been to check the subdivision of large estates suitable to closer settlement. As regards New South Wales, returns from the leading centres in each district show that the pro cess of cutting up the larger estates has practically ceased. A few smaller properties have been sold in blocks, principally to adjoining holders, but the movement towards subdivision which was general a few years ago has stopped for the time. A few districts report that no estates large enough for subdivision are left, but generally the stoppage is ascribed to the finan- cial stringency caused by the war, while in some centres the bad .season has been another deterrent. The check is, of course, only temporary, and with the return of normal conditions closer settlement will again become important. In the north generally subdivision is practically at a standstill. Part of the Conningdale estate in the New England district was for sale in seven blocks, aggregating 5,200 acres, of which four were sold to adjoining owners. A few station properties were sold right out, and a few homestead farms changed hands. In the Warialda district there has been no subdivision, but it has been decided to subdivide some of the larger properties of which a few portions have already been sold privately. Holdings previously subdivided are being sold piecemeal, but the business is generally slack. In the south the situation is practically the same, most centres report- ing " nothing doing ". The Clifton estate. Young, which comprised 5,000 acres was divided among five buyers. Woodlyn, Beckour, was cut up into four farms and sold ; and Ringambil, jMirrool, is said also to have been sold for closer settlement. A few stations have sold, notably Willie Ploma, Gundagai, and Talbingo, Tumut, but generally there has been little busi- ness in this direction. In the Hillston district surveyors have been bus}- on the proposed railway from Griffiths to Hillston. A large area is expect- ed to be thrown open to closer settlement shortly and the construction of this line is bound to lead to a closer settlement of the central division In the west it is expected that subdivision will be resumed. AUSTRIA. AGRICULTURAL LABOUR IX DALMATIA. — Katjcky (M). Die landwiHschaftliche Lohnarhcit in Dalmatien. Der Arbeitsnachweis . Vienna, Year 1916, Part. 5. Dalmatia, which suffers permanently from a great scarcity of labour, is not only that one of aU the Austrian crown lands which is poorest in fertile land, but is also that in which wages are highest. INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 1 25 The high wages seem to be due to three causes : (i) The absence of a real labouring class. — This is due to the circum- stances that the peasants were, even before 18^8, free from all subjection ; that the Southern Slav institution of the " Hauskommission ", partially preserved, ensures to each man a share, however small, of landed property ; and that the extent of the common lands — pasturage and heath — provides even the poorest with the minimum indispensable to life. Further the nearness of the sea affords various sources of profit. In the time of Venetian rule the noble landowners already complained of the high wages, which, they alleged, made the profitable cultivation of vines impossible. This is the reason for the extraordinary extension of metayage in Dalmatia. That land should be farmed by the holder's family is the rule ; and holders who are not farmers, or who cannot cultivate their lands through the members of their f amihes, usually grant them on lease to metayers. In these conditions there is only a limited demand for wage-earn- ing labour. (2) The technical character of the agriculture. —- Dalmatia has always been a ^ine country, that is a country of intensive agriculture in which secondary crops are insignificant and most frequently much neglected, and live stock has little importance. The result has been an unscientific distribution of labour which entails sometimes unemployment, sometimes high wages, without relation to the conditions of life among the rural population in the seasons of their principal labours — those of the vintage and of weeding. The vintage can employ women and children, but weeding needs the strength of a grown man, and it is in the period in which it is practised that the highest wages are paid. When this season is past the need for labour is less, and wages sink to some extent, chiefly as regards the part of them paid in kind. 3) The emigration to America, Australia and New Zealand- which is principally caused by the crisis in viticulture. — The desire to emigrate has taken deep root and become inherent in the Dalmatian mentality. It ma3' be affirmed that ten per cent, of the agricultural population, that is some 50,000 persons who include the best elements of the Dalmatian people, are employed in foreign countries. The resultant and constant lack of labour cannot be counterbalanced by the use of machinery, for machines are not to be thought of in cultivating vines. The same limitation applies, except in a few districts, to the other crops, a fact sufiiciently explained by the configuration of the soil of Dalmatia. An occasional fall in the price of wines, such as occurred some ^-ears ago, was not followed by a noticeable fall in wages. Its only marked result was a recrudescence of emigration to America and an aggravation of the scarcity of labour. Mticulture depends on a permanent investment of capital and allows small scope to the adjustment of labour according to the probable yield. Therefore wages must be looked upon not as costs of production, properly so called, but rather as costs of upkeep for which there should be compensation in good years. The present war has caused on the whole an important rise in wages. 126 INFORMATION REI^ATINCx TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL At Ivissa in the middle of March 1914 they were from 5 to 5.50 crowns (i) a day, in addition to breakfast and a midday meal which included wine. Therefore for a working day, lasting from seven in the morning until five in the evening, the actual value of the wage was more than 8 crowns. In some cases it was even 10 crowns. The wage generally comprises the labourer's keep, valued at from 2 to 2.4 crowns a day, as well as from 1.20 to 2 crowns a day in cash. When several labourers of unequal strength, skill and energy are en- gaged together they usually receive a uniform wage. Cash wages and keep — that is total wages — vary greatly in different districts. Seasonal migrations to the Dalmatian vineyards are unimportant as compared to the need for labour. In the south Montenegrins have hitherto thus migrated to the Gulf of Cattaro and the Ragusa district. In the north and centre of Dalmatia there is, on the other hand, a seasonal migration of labour from Zagorje, the Dalmatian hinterland and the home of the valued Dalmatian servants. The population is here chiefly occupied by live stock and cereal farming and therefore lacks employ- ment at the exact time at which work is in full swing in the vine district. In Zagorje itself, where the conditions of existence are primitive, wages are much lower than elsewhere in Dalmatia, but as regards the work they provide the labourers of this district are far behind those of the coast dis- tricts and the islands. In Zagorje a rise in wages is also to be observed, for the cultivation of vines is gaining ground in the valleys which have a good exposure, and emi- gration is increasing steadily. Moreover the saw-works of the Bosnian for- ests and the cement factories of the coast have an undeniable attraction for the border populations. The construction of the proposed railways will have the effect of further raising wages. (i) I crown = about iO(^ a'l par. RUGGERI ALFREDO, gerente responsabile. (c) Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases, r. t,E Service de Protection contre les maladies des plantes ex les INSECTES nuisibles DANS LES DIVERS PAYS (The Present Organization of the Services for the Control of Plant Diseases and Insect Pests in the Different Countries). (1914, 350 pages, 4to) ; Prs. 400 2. Production et consomm-ition des Engrais Chimiques dams le mondb (Production and Consumption of Chemical Manures in the World). (Second Edition, 1914, 162 pages, 5 diagrams, 2 maps, i6mo) 3.50 3. Iages, in English, French and Italian ; illustrated) Frs. i — 2. I,ouis-Dop : lyE Present et l'Avenir de l'Institut International d'Agriculture (Conference) (Present and Future of the International Institute of Agriculture) (Address). (1912, 60 pat^es, i6mo) • i — 3. Santiago Aldonate : El Instituto Internacional de Agricultura y su importancia para la america i.atina, en especial para chile (con- ferencia) (The International Institute of Agriculture and its Importance for Latin America, especially for Chile). (1913, 30 pages, i6mo) (Address). . . • i — II. Publications not for Sale. 1. Conference Internationale de 1905 pour la crEation d'un Institut International d'Agriculture (International Conference of 1905 for the Foundation of an Inter- national Institute of Agriculture), (1905, 254 pages, 4to). 2. ACTES DES Assemblies GEnErales des annees 1908, IQ09, 1911, 1913 (Proceedings of the General Assemblies of 1908. 1909, 1911 and 1913). (Four volumes, 8vo., one i6mol. 3. Proces-verbaux du ComixE Permanent des annEes 1908, 1909, 1910, 1911, 1912, 1913 fProces-verbaux of the Permanent Committee, 1908, 1909, 1910, 1911. 19x2, 1913, 1914 and 1915). (Five volumes, 8vo., and two i6mo). 4. Rapports et Etudes du Bureau de la Statistique GEnErale (Reports and Studies of the Bureau of General Statistics) (1911, 260 pages, Svo). 5. The Science and Practice of Farming during 1910 in Great Britain. (646 pages, i6mo). 6. Etude sur les recensements de la population .\gricole, les salaires de la main- d'ceuvre rurale et les cour-ants d'Emigration dans les diffErents Etats ( study on the Census Returns of the Agricultural Population, the Wages of Rural Ie >eixt with each order (5) In case of change of address, the subscrit>'-T • requested to notifv the Publishing ftf Rllr»»ni1 t1li» TnetJtllf<> f<->ril7arHinu aHHroc. toV.^1 5" 5r H' '^-5=^ > J^ INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE Bureau of Economic and Sociai, Intei,I/IGEnce INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (MONTHLY BXnXETIN OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL INTELLIGENCE) VOLUME LXXIV. 8th. YEAR: NUMBER 2 FEBRUARY, 1917. ROME PRINTING OFFICE OF THE INSTITUTE I917 Publications ot the International Institute of Agriculture. r. Publicatiofls for Salei „ Anoual Sloett A. — MONTHLY OK WEEKLY PUBLICATIONS gubwrlptlon numble I. International Crop Report and AGRicuLTUR-iL Statistics {Bulletin — — of Agricultural and Commercial Siatistics), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian, i6mo Frs. 6 0,60 a. International Review of the Science and Practice of Agriculture (Monthly Bulletin of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian. (Each number consists of about x8o pages, i6mo) » i8 3 — 3. International Review of Agricultural Economics (Monthly Bulletin of Economic and Social Intelligence), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian. (Each number consists of about 150 pages, i6mo) i8 3 — Subscription to all three Bulletins • 36 B. — HALF-YEARLY PUBLICATIONS. 1. Statistical Notes on Cereals. Studies on yeld, trade, consumption and prices, with rates of ocean freight , Frs. 1,50 2. The International Movement of Fertilisers and Chemical Products useful to Agriculture » 1,50 C. — YEAR BOOKS. I Annuaire International de Statistique .Agricole pour 1910 (Intti national Year Bocik of Agricultural Statistics, 1910). (1912, XL, VII] -(-327 pages, i6mo) Frs. 5 — Do. Vol. II, Years 191 1-1912. (1914, XXXIV + 624 pp. r6mo) . ... • 5 — Do. Vol. Ill, Years 1913-1914. (1915, XI^ satisfactorily sold. The work was in this year undertaken rather late, but after the harvest there were constituted in the west of the island societies for the co-operative sale of wool and lambs and for community breeding. In other parts of the island the farmers' institutes and the breeding associations became busy over the same problem. Efforts are being made to combine all local societies under the Sheep Breeders' Association, thus placing all the work on the producers. During the wdnter a representative of the Federal Live Stock Branch gave a number of demonstrations on boxing fleeces, and pointed out how wool might be increased in value by proper care during the winter. This department agreed to do the grading in 1916 as in the previous year, and stations for receiving the wool were opened at Summer- side and Charlottetown. The chief obstacle to progress seems to be the time farmers have to wait for payment, for they used to sell the wool directly to merchants for cash. One of the bankers has however agreed to help the associations. In 1916, 369 farmers took advantage of the organization. Altogether 28,302 pounds of wool or 4,411 fleeces were sold, for a total price of % 10,949.47. The prices of the different grades varied from 43 cents a pound for medium clothing to 10 cents a pound for tags. Province of Quebec. — The Wool Growers' and Sheep Breeders' Asso- ciations in Quebec have again successful^ graded and marketed their wool. In order to facilitate the work and improve the quality of the product instructors have gone through the province and explained to the farmers the rules they must follow in preparing their wool for sale, shearing etc. : Six hundred and forty-seven new members have been added since 1915 to the associations ; a new association has been formed in Megantic count}^ and the total output of wool was 169,839 pounds in 1916, showing an increase of 65,647 pounds as compared with 1915. The wool was sold in 1916 for S 71,092.70. Medium and fine medium combing grades sold at 43 cents a pound, black and gray and rejects at 38 cents. The average price for all grades, including rejects, was 41.8 cents a pound. These prices were all F. O. B. at the despatching points. Since local prices for ungraded wool ranged from 31 to 35 cents a pound, a gain of 7 to 12 cents a pound, or 40 per cent., had been secured. The associations are on a f)urely co-operative basis. The membership fees are based on the amount of business which each member does with the association. Four cents a fleece has been found to be sufficient to cover all expenses. The results obtained have been an improvement in the quality of the wool and in its preparation for sale, and its marketing at higher prices. THE CO-OPERATIVE SAXE OF WOOL 23 The followdng figures show the production of single associations. Association Number of Pounds Produced Pontiac -. . Compton Richmond Sherbrooke District of Bedford Stanstead District of Beauharnois Argenteuil Megantic Total . 51.564 ^2 24.471 Vz 17.567 16.885 16,621 V2 14.252 13.350 V2 11,191 3.937 169,840 As regards the proportion in which the different grades were produced it is enough to state that medium combings account for 49.4 per cent, and low medium combings for 34.5 per cent, of the total quantity. The following are further data as to the associations and their produc- tion and sale. Association Number of Members Number of Fleeces Average Weight per Fleece Average Price per Fleece Average Price per Pound Pontiac Coniplon Richmond Sherbrooke District of Bedford . . Staxistead District of Beauharnois. Argenteuil Megantic 282 167 133 153 125 "3 107 49 1,617 7,216 3,489 2,364 2,238 2,226 1.965 1.545 1,481 486 23,010 Pounds 7.02 7.06 7-43 7-53 7.42 7.22 8.79 7-75 8.1 7-59 F3.04 3.00 3.10 3-19 3.08 3.06 3.62 3.10 3-45 318 42.8 cents 42.4 » 41.7 » 42.3 » 41.5 » 42-3 » 41. 1 » 40.0 » 42.5 » 41.8 24 CANADA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Nova Scotia. — The co-operative selling of wool was undertaken in two counties of Nova Scotia in 1916, in Antigonish and Guysboro. In both the Department of Agriculture has representatives who organize the work. In Guysboro merely a beginning was made, the total sale amounting to a little less than 2,000 pounds. In Antigonish it was the second year in which wool was sold co-operatively, and about 15,400 pounds were graded and sold. The average price received was 41 ^/g cents a pound. The expenses amounted to slightly more than half a cent a pound. REGENCY OF TUNIS. NATIVE THRIFT SOCIETIES IN 1915. OFFlCIAIv SOURCE: Direction Generale des finances: Compfe rendu des op<'rafions des soctefes indigenes de pievoyance en 1915. [Financial Statement as to the Work of the Native Thrift Societies in 1915). Txuiis, 1916. The native thrift societies, to which all native agriculturists are obliged to belong, date from 1901. In those days there was question only of an experi- ment, and in 1905 onl}^ fifteen societies were at work. The benefits of the scheme were extended to the whole regency by a decree of 20 May 1907. The first article of this decree states that the Tunisian societies are enterprises of "agricultural mutual aid" — thus presuming for them a large programme of collective activitj^ — and specifies their power to form among their mem- bers agricultural co-operative associations. Article 21 lays down that such co-operdtive societies may enjoy the benefit of special advances from the sums annually due to the Bank of Algeria, exactly as do the planters' co-operative societies. The thrift societies play, towards the co-operative societies and in respect of these advances, exactly the role of the district banks of agricultural credit. But the Tunisian legislature has aimed especially at organizing credit for natives. The decree states verj^ clearly in the first place that loans are to be made exclusively to members of the thrift societies (articles 3 and 13) . These loans are in ;the form of seeds and of specie : the members can borrow even to extinguish prior debts, if necessary, on the security of mort- gages, so that they can at once free themselves from dependence on usurers. Further the decree of 20 May 1907 is concerned with providing the thrift societies with the resources necessary to their credit operations : it deducts from an advance of one million francs (i) made by the Tunisian govern- ment to the Bank of Algeria a sum of 50,000 francs as reserved to these societies ; and to this a decree of 26 January 191 1 adds the half of the an- nual dues. From these sums the societies can receive free advances equal 3 (i) I franc = <) — i/ at par. 26 REGENCY OF TUNIS - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION to half the sum of the centimes additional to taxes which they have col- lected as assessments. Since these resources may be insufficient, the same decree of 26 January 191 1 authorizes the societies to open current credit accounts in quarters approved bj' the Director of Finances. It also deter- mines the procedure for the realization of long or short term loan operations, whether secured by a mortgage or not. The relief given by Tunisian thrift societies should be noted. It is limited in its scope and may not be granted directly. Article 10 states that in the case of a famine the societies may make advances, which are repay- able, to the necessitous ; and that it will subsequently be the part of the government to remit to the borrowers, at the request of the societies, all or part of the advances so made. The amount of the assessments of centimes additional to the native taxes varies in the different societies from 5 to 17 per cent, of such taxes. § I. Receipts The receipts of the native thrift societies which have increased their credit were in 1915 as follows : i) Recoveries on the credit of former societies Fr. 1,441.61 2) Additional centimes on mediba tax 6,746.53 3) Quota of the recoveries of temporar^'^ assess- , menta due to the native thrift societies 118,058.60 4) Additional centimes on canoiin tax on olive and date trees: Years prior to igio 3i4-i3 Years 1910 and later 72,351.08 5) Additional centimes on achonr tax : Years prior to 1910 748-37 1910 and later 87,692.05 6) Additional centimes on djerba tax 9,328.42 7) " " " mradjas " 2,561.21 8) Recover^' of costs of management and commissions: a) for loans of seeds 2,806.58 i 72,665.21 5,440.42 b) for mortgage loans 53,362.67 - 56,951.54 c) for advances to affiliated societies. . . 782,29 ) Total . . . Fr. 356,193-54 NATIVE THRIFT SOCIETIES 27 Independently of these receipts the societies recovered 3, 765, 887. 52 francs in 1915 of the amount of their loans, such sum being distributed as follow : i) Loans of seeds 1908-1909 Fr. 3;950-32 2) " " 1909-1910 4,308.48 3) " " 1910-1911 21,107.24 4) " " 1911-1912 7,450.10 5) " " 1912-1913 137.005.94 6) " " 1913-1914 228,949.56 7) " " 1914-1915 3,230,430.11 8) " maintenance 1912-1913 53-00 9) " " 1913-1914 36,986.00 10) " " 1914-1915 131,020.00 11) Mortgage loans 43,970.04 12) Advances to affiliated societies 5^.676.73 Total . . . Fr. 3,896,907.67 Carried forward from receipts increasing credit of societies 356,193.54 Total sum of receipts in 1915 Fr. 4,253,101.21 § 2. Credit account of the societies on 31 December 1915. Since no expenditure in 1915 had diminished the amount of the re- ceipts increasing the credit of the societies these amounted to the net sum of ; Fr. 356,193-54 Add to this the amount of the scx:ieties' credit when the books of the previous year were closed 4,595,721.89 The total credit of native thrift societies on 31 Dec- ember 1915 was therefore Fr. 4,951,915.43 28 REGENCY OF TUNIS - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION This sum was distributed as follows : i) In hand in specie Fr. 2) Ivoans of seeds in 1908-1909 still to be recovered 1 909-1 910 1910-1911 " 1911-1912 " 1912-1913 " 1913-1914 " 1914-1915 " in 1912-13 " 1913-19^4 " 1914-1915 12) Mortgage loans 13) Sums advanced to affiHated societies 14) Sums spent before 31 December 1915 on loans of seeds in 1915-16, not 3'et distributed among the 3) ' 4) ' 5) ' 6) 7) ' 8) ' 9) ' ' maintenanc 10) ' ' " II) ' borrowing societies. 1,514.073.48 49,709-37 28.190.53 04,57875 980.16 466,176.01 199,333-54 3,280,695.68 58,173-98 30,003.70 4,086,450.64 1,577,232.70 31,666.16 916,313.88 Total Fr, 12,333,578.5s From this must be deducted : i) Sum due to the Revictiialling Account (i) and advanced for the loans of seeds in 1914- 1915 I^r. 3,295,212.51 2) Sum due to the State and advanced for the loans of maintenance in 1914-1915. . Fr. 4,086,450.64 Remainder . 7,381,663.15 Fr. 4,951,915.43 (i) See the arlicle on the "Revictualling Accoiuit" in our issue of June 1916, page 113. NATIVE THRIFT SOCIETIES 29 § 3. General observations on the work of the societies in 1915. i) Receipts. — The results obtained by the native thrift societies in the matter of receipts during 1915 may be considered satisfactory, for it should be remembered that the harv^est in certain districts left much to be desired owing to drought and hail, and that the state of war has caused special con- ditions. The net amount of the credit of the societies. was 4,951,915.43 francs on 31 December 1915, and this sum has since been surpassed. This capital surpasses that anticipated at the foundation of the so- cieties, namely four million francs ; but it was nevertheless inadequate to the needs of the season 1914-1915, during which the societies were obliged to accept State aid in order to ensure the loans of seeds and maintenance to the natives, which loans constitute their first and their chief object. It must however be anticipated that the societies will soon, in addi- tion to their present provision of necessary credit to various enterprises of mutual aid, be called upon to help other organizations ; which will doubt- less arise from a need for economic expansion subsequent to the war. The societies should therefore continue to observe the principles of economy and prudence which they have followed liitherto. In consti- tuting reserve funds for future needs the}^ give a salutar^^ example in thrift to their members. In order not to compromise the success of their enter- prise they are careful always to be sure that their advances will be repaid. 2) Loans of Seeds and of Maintenance. — In the farming year 1914-1915 the loans of seeds represented the sum of 6,511,125.79 francs, those of main- tenance 4,217,470.79 francs. The prices were by quintal (i) 34.50 francs for wheat, 24.40 francs for barley, 34 francs for beans and 23.91 francs for maize. These prices should be considered satisfactory for they include the price of sacks and all costs of management, transport, storage, guarding etc. The loans of seeds were represented in early years by the following sums : Season 1907-08 25,628.70 - 1908-09 1 .750,360.39 1909-10 670,563.42 - 1910-11 1,737,52349 - 1911-12 • 55,620.80 - 19^2-13 1,786,550-37 - 1913-14 451-17582 The loans of maintenance amounted to : in 1908-09 381,960.81 in 1910-11 118,465.72 in 1912-T3 5S>435-48 and in 1913-14 83,459.75 (i) I quintal =: 220 lbs 30 REGENCY OF TUNIS - CO-OPERA.TION AND ASSOCIATION Although the cereal harvest in 1915 was in general good, certain dis- tricts which had suffered from drought or hail applied for loans which were granted to them. A total expenditure of 1,566,749 francs — the price of 32,899 quintals of wheat and 24,297 quintals of barley — was thus incurred. In distributing this grain the administrators aimed especially at buy- ing cereals in the districts in which they were to be distributed, a procedure which had the double advantage of furnishing borrowers with seeds suited to their local climatic conditions and of considerably reducing the costs and difficulties of transport. Unfortunately it could rarely be applied, for there is usually a lack of cereals in the districts in need of loans. 3) MortgaQe Loans. — The native thrift societies haX'e continued, in view of the continuation of the state of war, to abstain on principle from lend- ing on m.ortgages. In the exceptional case however of five requests for loans, made by the natives of Nefzaoua before the war, the total sum of 38,789.95 francs was lent in 1915. During the 3'ear 1914-1915 " small mortgage loans of maintenance " were instituted in the caidate of Sousse in order to allow small proprietors to obtain food without recourse to usur\-. In the period from 5 February 1915 to 14 August 1916 forty-two such loans were made of sums between twenty and 500 francs, totalling 2,310 francs. 4) Co-operative Associations. — In spite of great difficulties, due espe- cialh" to an insufficient staff and the obstacles placed by the war in the way of providing industrv^ with primary and other material, most of the co-oper- ative societies affiliated to the native thrift societies have developed their activity in 1915. Independently of the immediate aid thex' have been able to give their members by placing at their disposal the capital they need, charging far less than the usual rate of interest, these organizations have accustomed the native artizans and traders to co-operation, that indispensable condi- tion of indu.strial and commercial progress. The advances they made amoimted to 41,185.29 francs in 1913 and to 23,790 francs in 1914, and rose in 1915 to 115,987.49 francs. This sum does not include the numerous advances made by the Revictualling Account to various native enterprises, and especially to the Laboratory of Industrial and Commercial Experiments in order to allow this institution to ensure the activity of its various workshops and furnish important mi- litary supplies to the Intendance. MISCELIvANEOUS INFOR]\L\TION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. BRITISH INDIA. I. CO OPERATON IX TRAVANXORP: (i). The State of Travancore in Southern India adjoins the province of Madras and has an area of 7091 square miles. In 190T the population was 2,952,157, having increased b}- 15 per cent, in the foregoing decade. Tra- vancore ranks fourth among native Indian States as regards area and third as regards population. Provision for co-operation in Travancore is contained in a regulation of 4 April 1914, and in the rules under Section 42 of this regulation which were issued on 17 November 1915. On 8 July 1916 twenty-three co-operative societies had been regis- tered, one of them being a bank which included among its members not only individuals but also societies, and had for its object the financing of the latter. Of the remaining twent^^-two societies two were for production and distribution, one for production only and two for distribution only, while the other seventeen v»'ere credit societies all of which except one w^ere formed on the Raffeisen model and on the basis of unlimited liability. Since all these societies had been registered towards the end of the official year, which begins in the middle of August, only a few had actually started work. The bank, the producing and distributing society, one of the societies for distribution only and seven of the credit societies were however in full working order although they had not yet accomplished much. All but one of the credit societies are intenderl to help agriculturists, who seem, by all the evidence yet available, to take advantage of them. By Section 4 of the regulation of 4 April 1914 " the liability of a so- ciety, of which a registered society is a member, shall be limited ; the lia- bility of a society, of which the object is the creation of funds to be lent to its members, and of which no member is a register^ society, shall be I'l) The facts rc.ijar.liii,ii co oi;craliim in Travancore luue b.in communicated to u-: by M.-. O. Ciovinda I'iilai. R'-iislrar of Cooperative vSocieties in thi.- State. INKv^RMA/llOX RELATING TO CO-Ol'EKATION AND ASSUCIATIUX unlimited. Where the liabilit}' of the members of a society is Hmited by shares, no member, other than a registered society, shall hold more than such ]:)ortion of the share capital of the society as may be prescribed by the rules, subject to a maximum of one fifth ; or have a claim or interest in the shares of the society exceeding one thousand rupees (i) ". The minimum membership of a society, which includes no registered society among its members, is seven. Where the liability of the members of a registered society is not lim ited by shares, each member has one vote only. In the contrary case he has as many votes as are prescribed by the by-laws. Subject to any prior claim of the government in respect of land reve-, nue or any mioney recoverable as land revenue, or of a landlord in respect of rent or any money reco^-erable as rent, a registered society i? entitled in priority to other creditors, to enforce any outstanding demand for any- thing due to it from a member or past member : a) in respect of the supply of seed or manure or of the loan of money for the purchase of seed or ma- nure, upon the crops or other agricultural produce of such member or per- son at any time within eighteen months from the date of such supply or loan ; b) in respect of the svipply of cattle, fodder for cattle, agricultural or industrial implements or machinery, or raw materials for manufacture,- or of the loan of money for the purchase of any of the foregoing things, upon an^^ such things so supplied, or purchased in whole or in part from such loan, or any articles matiufactured from raw materials so supplied or purchased, at any time within three years from the date of such suppl}'' or loan. The liability of a past member for the debts of a registered society, as they existed at the time when he ceased to be a member, continues for a period of two years from the date of his ceasing to be a member. The estate of a deceased member is liable, for a period of one year from the time of his decease, for the debts of a registered society as they existed at the time of his decease. The government may remit any stamp duty with which instruments executed by or on behalf of a registered society may at any time be chargeable, as well as any fee payable under any law of registration. The Trivandnim Central Co-operative Bank, Limited, to which we have already alluded, aims at developing co-operative societies in Tra- vancore ; financing them and carrying on banking business with them ; controlling them when they have been affiliated to itself by careful and re- gular inspection ; and encouraging thrift, self-help, and mutual trust and confidence among its individual members. The capital of the bank is 100,000 rupees, made up of 1,000 shares of 100 rupees each. Not more than 500 shares may be allotted to members other than societies ; and no member may at any time hold more than ten shares. No member mav withdraw or transfer a share which he has not (i) I rupee = is. 4^. IXFORlVL\TION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 33 held for at least one year. Every transfer of a share must have the sanc- tion of the Board of Management and involves payment of a fee of 2 rupees. The value of each share is pa3'able in five instalments of 20 rupees each, the instalments being paid at intervals of at least three months. The funds of the society must be utilized primarily for the granting of loans to registered co-operative societies. lyoans may also be granted to members i) on the securit}^ of their deposits or on their paid-up share capital, not exceeding 90 per cent. ; 2) on the security of Government of India promissory notes ; 3) on the personal security of the borrower and two sureties from among the members. No loan to an individual member shall be granted in the first instance for more than three months, nor to a society member for more than two years ; but the Board of Management may from time to time grant exten- sion of loans, no extension exceeding the original period. The rate of in- terest charged on loans shall not exceed 9 14 P^^ cent, per annum and a rebate of 2 per cent, per annum shall be allowed on all punctual repayments. One fourth of the net profits of each year shall be carried to the credit of the reserve fimd. One eighth shall be paid as honorarium to the secre- tSLvy. Of the balance 10 per cent, shall be set apart to meet the charges of inspection, the remainder being divided among all the members, subject to a maximum of 12 per cent, per annum, according to the paid-up share capital held by them during the year. The reserve fund shall be one and indivisible : it shall not be drawn upon except to make losses good, and shall be invested as the registrar directs. This bank has now 85 members, namely 69 individual members and 16 societ}^ members — including 15 associations of agricultural credit. Hitherto its loans on personal guarantees have been negligible but it has lent to its society-members 27,560 rupees of which sum 27,310 rupees have not yet been repaid. Its paid-up share capital amounts to 8,340 rupees and its loans to the government to 29,800 rupees. The Trivandrum Co-operative Distributive Society, Limited, is a society of a different type. It has a capital of 5,000 rupees consisting of 1,000 shares of 5 rupees each. There is an entrance fees of six annas (i) a share. No member may hold in the first instance more than twenty shares ; but members may use the dividends earned by them in the purchase of addi- tional shares until they hold altogether a maximum of twenty-five. Profits must be disposed of as follows : one fourth shall be carried to the credit of the reserve fund ; a bonus, not exceeding 10 per cent, of the net profit or a maximum of 250 rupees a year, shall be paid to the secretary; out of the remaining profits a dividend not exceeding 7 ^ per cent, a year shall be paid on the paid-up share capital ; any balance shall be paid to the members as a bonus, proportionately to the purchases made by them. The following table shows the activity of agricultural co-operative societies in Travancore in the year which ended on 15 August 1916. ([) I anna = i penny. 34 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Activity of Agricultural Co-operative Societies in Travancorc. Kind of Society Number of Societies Number | Amount ^ ^'"^ of of I/jans S^ Indi- on \ p°: vidua! Personal ^ ,'f " ■Kt^^v, /^„„ 1 sold to Memb- Gua- ,, , ers rantees *^^^''- Pur- chase of Mem- bers Pro- ducts I,oans not repaid Paid up Share- Capital Costs of Admin- istra- tion Unliniitedi,iabilitj' Societies I » » » I Bull 16 )> » » » that is 32 traction engines at a total cost of about 500,000 francs (2;. The activity of the syndicate will affect twenty-two comnumes, and about 7,200 hectares of arable land fitted for the intensive culture of corn and sugar beetroot. The scarcity of agricultural labour in this dis- trict — as a result of the mobilization of Belgian workmen, the proximity of factories of war material and the prohibition to employ prisonners of war which was long in force — decided the agriculturists to use these new- methods of work as a matter of urgency. Counting the traction engines already bought by individuals outside the syndicate, there are now forty of these machines in the arrondissement of Pontoise, and the possibility of shortly using double that number ought to be realized. UNITED STATES. THE DEVEIvOPMENT OF THE CO-OPERATIVE ASSOCIATIONS CONTROI,l,ING DAIRY PRODUCl'ION IN THE UNITED STATES FROM 1906 TO 1916 ~ Hoard's Dairyman, Fort Atkinson, 3 November 1916. The movement in favour of co-operative societies of breedeis and pro- ducers in order to inspect the individual production of milch cows, for the purpose of selection, began in Michigan in 1906 and has in ten years spread through thirty-eight States. To-day there are 346 of these associations. (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. (2) 1.261 1 francs ■-= is at par. 38 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION They are most numerous in the following States Wisconsin 52 New York. ...-'. 47 Vermont 38 Iowa 23 Minnesota 22 Ohio 20 Pennsylvania ... 19 Oregon 15 Illinois 12 Maine 11 New Hampshire . . ii Michigan 10 The following table shows the complete development of these associa- tions since they were founded. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Development of the Co-operative Associations inspecting the Production of Milch Cows in the United States from i July 1906 to 1 July 1915. Number of associations active in states 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 Michigan Miiine New York Vermont I 4 2 3 I 5 4 I 2 2 I 9 I 4 3 3 8 5 3 ID 0 I I I I 3 6 9 ID 4 2 10 0 I I 0 I 4 3 3 I I I 2 2 4 5 18 II 8 4 8 0 2 2 0 3 .3 I 7 I I 0 2 2 I 2 I 4 4 21 17 7 4 II 3 I 2 I 3 2 0 10 I I 0 2 2 I 2 I 3 5 29 28 8 5 24 2 I 7 4 2 7 0 9 4 7 I 3 0 I 2 I 2 2 I I 2 I I 3 8 35 33 13 7 37 3 0 14 5 4 3 I II 8 II I 0 0 0 3 0 I 3 I 3 0 0 I I 10 II 47 38 23 California 9 Wisconsin Ntbraska Colorado . Pennsylvania Ohio Maryland Illinois Washington Minnesota Oregon Utah Massachusetts Virginia Kansas Kentucky Missouri New Jersey ...... West Virginia Connecticut North Carolina .... I,ouisiana South Dakota .... Nevada Arizona Rhode Island . . .* . . Icaho Mississippi Montana 52 4 0 19 20 7 3 12 22 II 15 0 4 2 I 7 I 2 4 3 6 0 0 3 0 2 2 2 2 I I I Tofal . . . I 4 6 25 40 64 62 100 163 210 346 Part 11: Insurance and Thrift UNITED STATES. STATE HAIL INSUR.XNCE IN NORTH DAKOTA. SOURCES : Biennial Report to the Thirteenth I^egislative Assembly of the hail Commissioner ON Hail Insurance for the term ending, December 31st, 191 2, Bismarck, N. D. Biennial Report to the Fourteenth I,egislative Assembly of the Hail Commission ON Hail Insurance for the term ent)ing December 31ST, 1914. Journal Publish- ing C"., Devil's I,akc, N. D. State Hail Insurance I93^^-^9 Paid agents for adjusting same 2,447.62 Clerk hire 2,160.00 Postage 43-00 Printing 103.40 ►Advertising 9.95 Refund to Morton County 4.80 .Sl)ecial adjuster's expenses .53-25 Total amount of disbursements during the year 1912 63,164.26 Balance cash on hand Jan. ist, 1913 $3-175% 48 UNITED STATES - INSURANCE AND THRIFT Policy exhibit. Number of policies issued in 1912 2.505 Number of losses reported in 1912 433 Number of losses allowed during 1912 . . . 411 Number of policies effected 391 Total amount of losses allowed for season 1912 $105,339.54 Expenses paid for adjusting same 2,447.62 making it cost 2.32 % to adjust the losses. Approved adjustments were paid at 55 % of loss allowed in 1912. Income. Cash in hands of State Treasurer Dec. 31st, 1912 .... $3,175.89 Cash received as payment of policies issued in 1913. . . . 27,214.37 Total amount received during the year . . . $30,390.26 Disbursements. Paid losses incurred during 1912 ... . . . $1,559.42 Paid losses incurred during 1913 24.890.78 Paid agents for adjusting same 694.53 Clerk hire 1,927.50 Postage 53-86 Printing 377-00 Express 21.22 Total disbursements during 1913 . . . $29,524.31 Balance cash on hand Dec. ist, 1913 $865.95 Policy exhibit. Number of policies issued in 1913 733 Number of losses reported in 1913 91 Number of losses allowed in 1913 89 Number of policies effected 88 Total amount of losses allowed for the season of 1913 . . $28,284.98 Expense paid for adjusting same 694.53 making it cost 2.45 % to adjust the losses. Approved adjustments were paid at 88 % of loss allowed for 1913. STATE HAII< INSURANCE IN NORTH PAKOTA 49 1914. — Income. Balance, cash in hands of State Treasurer Dec. ist, 1913 . $865.95 Cash received as payment of poHcies issued in 1914. . . . 27,771.72 Total amount received during the year . , . $28,637.67 Disbursements. Paid W. D. lyukins, official adjuster Williams County for adjusting one loss for 1913 10.00 Paid losses incurred during 1914 . . . . . . 24,985.39 Paid agents for adjusting 1914 losses .... 871.71 Paid clerk hire 1,800.00 Paid postage 89.98 Paid printing 80.67 Paid miscellaneous supplies 10.25 Paid for publishing notices of condition of Hail Department for 1913 14.09 Total disbursements during year 1914 . . ' $27,862.09 Balance cash on hand Dec. rst. 1914 775-58 POUCY EXHIBIT. Number of policies issued in 1914 761 Number of losses reported in 1914 114 Number of losses allowed in 1914 113 Number of policies effected 114 Total amount of losses allowed for season of 1914 .... $38,439.07 Expense paid for adjusting same 871.71 making it cost 2.26 % to adjust the losses. Approved adjustments were paid at 65 % of loss allowed for 1914. BRITISH INDIA. CATTI.E INSURANCE IN BURMA. by A. E. English, I. G. S. Registrar of Co-operative Societies, Burma. After some six years' experience in the introduction of co-operative credit into the various districts of Burma it became clear that one of the chief causes of indebtedness was the loss of plough cattle by death from disease or accident. In accordance with the obvious fact that insurance providing for the replacement of cattle so lost, and for the evolution of a spirit of corporate responsibility for the tending of cattle, was preferable to the mere granting of credit to replace such dead beasts, efforts were made to discover a simple and suitable system of insurance of plough cattle suitable for Burma. The matter was complicated because Burma has a variety of climates, crops, crop seasons, cattle and systems of cultivation and methods of cattle tending. Speaking broadly there is the southern wet zone where rice is cultivated in the rains (June to November), where the rainfall varies from 80 to 150 inches and where it is never cold ; then there is the northern wet zone comprising five hilly districts where the rainfall averages 80 in- ches and rice is the main crop, and where there is a distinct cold season; and between these there is the central dry zone with a rainfall varying from 15 to 40 inches, liable, where not irrigated, to serious droughts and having for two or three months a very high temperature (100 to 115 degrees. F.). In this dry area there is a large variety of crops. On the uplands are grown cotton, sessamum, ground-nut, jowar etc. in the rainy months (June to November) ; sugar-cane, rice, onions and pulses are grown throughout the year under irrigation; and pulses, potatoes, chillies, and other miscellaneous crops are raised in alluvial land along the river in the dry weather (November to April). In the north and south wet zones the buffalo was till recently the prin- cipal draught beast. In the Delta districts, however, the buffalo's suscepti- biHty to rinderpest has brought about an ever extending use of bullocks, and there is now a large annual export of bullocks bred in the dry zone to IvOwer Burma for ploughing and carting purposes. In the northern wet CATTI,E INSURANCE IN BURMA 5 1 zone, where soils are heavy and weeds strong and where cattle are also used for timber extraction, the buffalo remains in favour, but the village herds are still Uable to terrible epidemics of rinderpest. The S3^stems of cattle tending differ widely in the wet and dr>' zones. In the southern wet zone the grazing ground system is the rule. Each vil- lage has an area, generally uncultivable, allotted to it for grazing purposes, and in this area the village cattle have to pick up a precarious living. In many cases these areas are in the rains seas of mud, covered with a trampled growth of coarse muddy grasses. They provide the best possible means for spreading infectious disease and the cattle that have to exist on them naturally have an excellent chance of dying from disease, starvation, or exposure. The mortality in such districts is very high and many cultivators regard four years as the working life of an imported beast. It is probable that a premium of 15 per cent would not cover the risk in this part of the country. In the northern wet zone the area of " jungle " available for grazing is as a rule much larger and there is a certain amount of segregation during grazing. Violent epidemics are unusual except from the unusually infectious disease of rinderpest. These jungles, however, contain a danger from which the southern grazing ground is free and that is wild cattle — bison, deer and pigs from which anthrax and other diseases are undoubtedly communicated to tame cattle. If insurance be ever extended to the northern districts a high rate of premium will be necessary. In the dry zone districts the custom is that draught cattle, which are almost entirely btdlocks, are stall fed, while cows and calves are grazed in herds in scrub jungle near the villages. The stall fed draught cattle are carefully fed and housed and seldom suffer » from epidemics. The breeding herds are tended with much less care and suffer from scanty fare, bad housing and dirty pens. In a season of drought the cows and calves die in large numbers. Disease also kills them off in quantities. Except in a few very restricted areas cows are not used by the Burmese for milking purposes and it is somewhat surprising that with the treatment they get they produce such good draught stock. In view of the above conditions it was obvious that the first experiments in insurance must be restricted to draught cattle, and to such cattle only in selected dr>' zone districts where the stall feeding and careful tending of such animals was the rule. The Registrar of Co-operative Societies sug- gested the adoption of a system whereby animals would be valued half- yearly and insured for a half-year at a time, and it was decided to hmit the experiment in the first instance to five adjacent districts, i. e. Mandalay, Shwebo, Sagaing, Kyaukse and Meiktila, in all of which such statistics as were available showed that violent epidemics of infectious disease among draught cattle were unusual. Co-operative cattle insurance was discussed at the Provincial Agri- cultural and Co-operative Conference held at Mandalay in 191 1, after six mutual co-operative cattle insurance societies had been formed, and it was resolved that insurance was desirable and feasible and that the scheme should be proceeded with. In the period between July 191 1 and June 1912 seventeen, and in the year 1912-1913 thirty-six societies were formed. It 52 BRITISH INDIA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT then became evident that in the early years, to render certain payment of part at any rate of the indemnity, reinsurance was essential. It also appeared that insurance would not become really popular unless deaths from rinderpest were covered. The whole subject was again discussed at the Agricultural and Co- operative Conference held at Mandalay in August 1913 : and in a meeting which over 300 chairmen of agricultural credit societes attended it was then resolved that the premium rate should be raised from 3 ^/g per cent, to 5 per cent, per annum, and that rinderpest deaths should be covered ; that a central reinsurance society was essential ; and that to eliminate the risk of fraud membership of cattle insurance societies should be re- stricted to persons who are members of co-operative credit societies. The sanction of the Secretary of State for India to the grant, by way of an interest free loan, to the central reinsurance society of assistance to enable it to meet indemnities in the early years, was received early in 1915. The amount to be drawn in any one year is not to exceed Rs. 25,000 (i) and repayments are to be made from the sixth year onwards from the central society's reserve fund. Cattle insurance was again discussed at the Agricultural and Co-oper- ative Conference held at Mandalay in August 1915 ; and it was resolved that the central reinsurance society should be formed, that in the five districts to which operations were at present to be confined every credit society should form an annexed cattle insurance society, and that for purposes of supervision a cattle insurance society should be admitted into the union to which the credit society, to which it was annexed, belonged. The Upper Burma Central Co-operative Cattle Reinsurance Society, Limited, was registered in August 1915. The membership consists of some fifteen honorary members — persons interested in co-operative and agricul- tural improvement — and of affiliated village cattle insurance societies. It receives half the premia paid to societies by members and insures half the risk undertaken by such societies. Indemnities due are paid by the manager on receipt of a cattle death report giving full details. It is managed by a general meeting, committee and a manager. For the present the registrar is acting as honorary manager. To safeguard the interests of government, a government representative is a member of the general meeting and has five votes. It has a general fund, consisting of the current year's premium income, and a reserve fund consisting of the net proceeds of past years. The latter fund is banked with the National Bank of India and the general fund is kept in the Upper Burma Central Co-operative Bank. Societies submit to the manager of the central society half-yearly statements show- ing the names of members and number, descriptions and value of cattle insured. The by-laws of the village mutual cattle insurance societies are based on those used by French mutual societies. There are the usual exceptions of deaths from war, theft etc., and societies do not pay indemnities where (i) I rupee = IS Ad, CATTI,E INSURANCE IN BURMA 53 the sanitary' regulations as to contagious disease have been broken. Mem- bership is restricted. Valuations are made half-yearly by three experts appointed yearly by the general meeting. Substitution is permitted if values are equal. The premium rate is 5 per cent, per annum payable half- yearly in March and September. Funds are deposited with the local credit society at call. Deaths have to be vouched for by the experts and the society" only pays two thirds of the value insured. The skin and flesh belong to the society which sells them, if saleable. Hence the owner stands to get two thirds of the value insured, whether his animal dies of a contagious or non-contagious disease. Societies are managed by a general meeting and a committee. Pending the formation of the central reinsurance society, the form- ation of village societies was restricted, and in the period July 1914 to June 1915 only seven such societies were registered. In the year July 1915 to June 1916, 247 societies have been registered and a further considerable increase is expected in the coming year. Of the 305 village societies in exist- ence on 30 June 1916 about a hundred had not yet become afSHated to the central society. The bulk of the new societies registered only started business in March or April 1916, and results cannot therefore be appreciated till October next, at the earliest. Judging by the steady accumulations of funds by those societies which have been working for several years, and in view of the fact that onty two thirds of the value is paid in indemnity, there is ground for believing that the 5 per cent, rate of premium is unncessarily high and somewhat likely to hinder the progress of insurance. Burma has, however, except in the northern wet zone, enjoyed a remarkable measure of immunity from rinderpest in the last ten years. As it is yet too early to say that this immunity is due to the improvement in veterinary control, and not rather to good fortune and disease cycles, it is perhaps better to err on the safe side in the matter of the premium rate. Many of the villages in which cattle insurance societies are formed are in tracts only partially served by the Post Office, and there is conse- quently difficulty both in remitting premia to the central society and in the pa3^ment of indemnities. Such difficulties of course check expansion but they will decrease with time. In three areas during the year ending 30 June 1916 epidemic disease — anthrax — appeared and accounted for mortality above the average. There is every indication that the adoption of co-operative cattle insurance in these five districts where co-operative credit is already well estabhshed will promote better protection of cattle against disease, better relations with the Veterinary Department, and a decrease in mortality. The statements given below show results to 30 June 191 6. It has not been necessary to draw upon the government guarantee loan. Cattle are at present often undervalued : they average about Rs.30 per head whereas a truer average would be Rs. 40. The proceeds of skin and flesh have exceeded expectations. The societies are audited, along with the agricultural credit societies 54 BRITISH INDIA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT to which they are annexed, by the staffs of society paid and government auditors, supervision being done by the inspectors maintained by unions of credit societies. It is 3^et early to gauge results or to prophesy, but it may be said that the principles of insurance appeal to the Burnian and that in the districts where a commencement has been made the co-operative idea has taken firm hold. Thus in the Kyaukse district there is one agricultural co-oper- ative society (credit) for every 1050 acres of cultivated land, while, in ad- dition to co-operative credit, considerable progress with co-operative pro- duction and sale has been made in the districts of Mandalay, Sagaing and Shwebo. If the high premium rate do not act as a deterrent, and if minor difficulties connected with remittance can be eliminated, there is no reason apparent why co-operative insurance of cattle should not become firmly and widely established. Operations of Cattle Insurances Societies in Burma, On 30 June 1916 Amount of risk insured on 30-6-16 Premia collected during the year Numl)er of Animals-. Claims paid during year Cost of manage- ment during year Funds at end of year Amount of risk reinsured. Amount of premia Societies Mem- bers Insured on 30-6-16 I,ost during year for re- insurance. 305 5,045 Rs 287,051 Rs 9,737 7,929 75 Rs 685 Rs 219 Rs 10,671 Rs 113,050 Rs 4,022 II. Oferations of the Upper Burma Central Cattle Insurcmce Society. No. of affiliated Proportion of risk affiliated societies reinsured Amount of risk reinsured. Premia collected during year to 30-6-16 Number of animals covered by affiliated societies. Claims paid to affiliated societies. Cost of manage- ment. Funds in hand at end of year 30-6-1916 societies. Insured. I,ost. General Fund. Reserve Fund. 305 V2 Rs 113,050 Rs 4,022 6,209 37 Rs 247 Rs 148 Rs 2,113 1,513 Part III: Credit AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY. AGRICUI^TURAlv CREDIT IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA. OFFICIAIv SOURCES : Die I,andwirtschaft in Bosnien und der Herzegovina {Agriculture in Bosnia and Herze- govina) Vienna, 1899. Verwaltungsberichte fur 1906- 1 911 {Government Reports for 1906-1911). OTHER SOURCES : V. Horowitz (E. R.) : Die Bezirkuncsunterstutzungsfonds in Bosnien und Herzegovina {The District Loan Funds in Bosnia and Herzegovina) Vienna, 1892. ScHMiD {Dr. F) Bosnien und Herzegovina unter der Verwaltung Oesterreich-Ungarns {Bosnia and Herzegovina under the Rule of Austria- Hungary) lycipzig, 1914. § I. RURAI. CREDIT IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA UNDER TURKISH DOMINATION. In the time of Turkish domination social and economic conditions in Bosnia and Herzegovina were Httle favourable to the development of cre- dit in general and completely opposed to that of agricultural credit. In the country the ruling s^'stem wa.s one of simple natural economy. Each farm sought itself to produce whatever it needed or desired solely from its own soil rendered fruitful by labour. Agricultural labourers made purchases on the market only exceptionally, when they could not supply their needs from the land they cultivated, as when they required colonial products, agricultural implements, cotton stuffs, etc. Such purchases were so limited 56 AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY - CREDIT that they accounted only for an unimportant circulation of money. Defec- tive means of communicaliou and the presence of the institution of the Za- droiiga contributed . much to the long preservation in Bosnia and Herzego- vina of natural economy in all its simplicity, after it had elsewhere been replaced by economic systems based on money. We should add that in these two vSlav provinces the development of agrictulural credit was impeded by the existence of jurisdictory relations feudal in type, which even today have not entirely disappeared and which mutually connect the feudatory agas and the kmeti agricultural labourers. In Bosnia and Herzegovina property in land is indeed not free even today but is subject to an almost feudal regime. It is burdened with the kmeti cultivators' rights of usufruct, which are unlimited as to time and condi- tions, so that if a holding be alienated the cultivator's usufruct persists unmodified by the change of ownership. The mere indication of such a state of affairs is enough to show that it has contributed and still contri- butes to impede the development of land credit in this country. Another hindrance to such development was the complete absence of a cadaster and of registers of land, in other woids of a basis for mortgage credit. For that matter the peasant of Bosnia and Herzegovina felt no great need for credit. If he wanted money he got it easily by selling the products of his land to some small dealer in the neighbouring town, from whom afterwards he bought what he required : otherwise he could not have ob- tained that very limited quantity of the products of agriculture or industry^ necessary to him. Sometimes indeed he had to have recourse to a loan, but it was always this same small dealer who became his banker. Such loans had three different forms : a) loans in specie were received ; h) manufactured products were bought for credit ; c) provisions were bought for credit generally in spring or summer, before the harvest. The peasant paid a grosch a month on the sums thus lent, that is to say lo per cent. The law established that the rate of interest should not sur- pass 12 percent, but this limitation was eluded by lumping the amount of the interest and the capital. Very often also it was agreed that the debt should be repaid not in specie but in kind, in other words in agricultural products of which the quantity was fixed by the deed of loan, which therefore crea- ted a contract truly contingent on risks. In the case of a purchase of provisions or manufactured products for credit, the interest attaching to the correspondent value in specie was con- sidered not as being separate but as swelling the sum wliich the debtor had to repay. The rate of this interest varied in the proportion in which the purchase price of the goods bought for credit surpassed the usual cash price by from 50 to 100 per cent. AGRICLTLTURAI, CREDtT IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGO\T:nA 57 The contract established whether interest should be paid in specie or in kind. In the latter case it was equivalent, when the debt had been incur- red by a purchase of provisions, to the difference between the quantity of provisions received on loan , and the quantity paid back when the term of the loan expired. Generally the latter surpassed the former quantity by from 50 to 100 per cent. The loans in specie might in certain respects be called agricultural loans for the peasants were the only class of the population who could obtain them, they sought them at least partl}^ for reasons inseparable from agriculture, and in greater or less proportion the}' repaid them with the products of the soil. The same cannot be said as to credit operations made with certain spe- cial funds, such as the funds of churches and mosques, those of the Vakouf properties and of the unions, those guaranteeing the property of wards, etc : None of the institutions managing these funds granted loans to peasants but only to traders and artisans. When however the middle of the century had been passed the Turkish govemmxcnt made a first attempt to encourage the development of agricul- tural credit, and formed the institutions known as menafi- sandonks. Founded in all the vilayets of Bosnia and Herzegovina they were specially intended to utilize their funds in granting loans wliich should favour the development of agriculture. Their funds were derived from a tax incum- bent on all the peasants and equivalent to a tenth of the value of all the products of the soil, exclusive of the usual tithe. At first the menafi sandonks only granted loans in kind, and in this res- pect they acted as real institutions of land credit. Later however they substituted loans in specie for loans in kind. Little by little they lost their special character as institutions for the encouragement of agriculture and were transformed into credit institutions. They granted loans gener- ally to government servants or to traders and hardly ever to peasants. Thus the intention of the law was defeated by facts. As regards the history of these special credit institutions, the first menafi sandouk was formed in 1863 by Mitad Pacha, vali of the vila3'et of the Danube. In 1865 a law was promulgated which decreed that they shotdd be founded in all the vila- yets of the Turkish empire. § 2 Development of agricuetural credit in bosnia and herzegovina after the austrian and hungarian occupation. The occupation of Bosnia and Herzegovina by Austria and Hungary contributed largely to the improvement in these two provinces of the con- ditions of agricultural credit, to which it gave a new impulse. In the first place the population, both floating and fi.Kcd, was ver}' per- ceptibly increased, by the added mihtary element which was very numerous in the early days of the occupation, and by the government servants who also were present in sufficiently important numbers. Especially the latter 58 AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY - CREDIT formed among the citizens of the country a special class, who in the e>dsting conditions were obliged to buy all the}' needed in the market with their mon- ey. The immediate consequence of this rapid and notable increase in the population was a corresponding increase in the price of all the goods in the market. Added to this first cause, which had an immediate effect on the econo- my of the country , was a second — the construction of new lines of com- munication. These had a propitious influence on the development of trade which they rendered more active, and not only the trade within every inhab- ited district in the country but also foreign trade. Thanks to these ele- ments of progress the general activity of the market was more and more in- tensified, the quantity of products on the market increased, and an economy based on cash gradually replaced natural economy in the country. Thus the indispensable and fundamental basis for credit was found. The institution of the land registers and of the cadaster, begun in the first per- iod of occupation and actively continued, finally completed the work un- dertaken for economic progres.-?, in that it gave the necessary basis to mort- gage credit. Special institutions of agricultural credit were founded, and they large- ly contributed to the improvement of the country's general economy. We wiU proceed to speak of them § 3. The institutions of rural credit. A. Mortgage Credit. The institution of land credit in Bosnia and Herzeogvina is due to the initiative of the Austrian and Hungarian government. In 1883 a first contract between the government and the Wiener Union- bank was drawn up for this purpose. By its terms this bank was bound to instal at Sarajevo a branch which should begin to afford land credit in the country. The government for its part engaged : i) to furnish this bank with all information relative to the solvency of debtors; 2) to authorize the post offices of the country' to receive the annual payments owed by debtors on behalf of the Wiener Unionbank. But the Wiener Unionbank afforded land credit only for three years. In 1886 it ceased to grant mortgage loans, thus obliging the government to enter into a new contract with the fund for the retirement of State employees. According to the rule of 1887 this fund makes loans of two kinds, as follows : a) Ordinary mortgage loans, that is loans of sums the use of which is not controlled. Loans of this kind ma}' be made only when the mortgaged land is entered in the land registers. b) Special mortgage loans granted to the kmeii (cultivators) in order that they may free the lands they till from feudal burdens due to the aga AGRICULTURAL CREDIT IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA 59 (owners) or in order that they may make some improvement on such lands. These loans are granted even without the guarantee of the special registra- tion by the ^wc?^z of the lands they till in the land registers. The fund how- ever controls the debtor's use of the money be borrows. The loans are always for long terms (ten years) and the. rate of interest does not surpass 6 per cent. The fund may not grant loans of which the value is more than laalf the estimated value of the mortgaged lands. In 1889 however the society managing this fund ceased to act as an institution of mortgage credit. All its credit was thereupon transferred to another and newly formed institution which carried on credit operations under the name of Mortgage Bank of Bosnia and Herzegovina. The contract between this bank and the government has the following terms : a) The mortgage bank is authorized to issue mortgage bonds for a total value equal to tv/enty times the reserve fund which was at first 200,000 crowns (i). b) The .State engages to provide the mortgage bank with the capital necessary for effecting in the interests of the kmeii the operations necessary to freeing the lands they till from all feudal burdens owed to the aga. c) The government offices of taxes are bound to furnish the bank with all necessary information as to the solvency of debtors, from, whom also they are obliged to recover the annual payments due to the bank. d) The bank grants mortgage loans for long terms — ten to twenty years — charging interest at the rate of 6 per cent. The mortgage titles issued by the bank bring in 5 per cent. In 1895 the mortgage bank of which we have spoken was succeeded b}'- another institution having the same object and caMed Landesbanh fiirBo- snien und die Herzegoivina. The formation of this new institution and the supersession of the earlier one were due to the government's desire to augment circulating capital. With this aim the following measures were undertaken : i) The new bank was founded with a share capital of 10,000,000 crowns. 2) It was authorized to issue mortgage bonds up to a value thirty times that of its share capital. 3) It enjo3'S all the privileges previously granted to the mortgage bank. vSide by side with the credit institutions we have named, which emanat- ed from the government directly and therefore enjoyed special privileges and had a more or less official character — since they undertook credit tran- sactions under the State's direct superintendence — , others were formed by the initiative of private person.5. Their activity was much limited, yet it was nevertheless to some extent that of institutions of land credit. Among them were the various local banks, the Austrian and Hungarian banks, (i) I crown of gold = 10 — rf at par. 12 6o AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY - CREDIT certain special institutions disposing of their own funds, and private credi tors. The statistical data regarding land credit in Bosnia and Herzegovina are few and incomplete. From the official reports published before 1907 we learn onlj^ the total amount of the country's mortgage debt, no distinction being made among institutions and persons having such credit. It is only after 1907 that these statistics give us data relative to the different classes of mortga.ted). Speech, at the Second Italian Con- gress of Geography at Rome, September 1895. Rome, Bertero and Co. 1895. P.\or.i (Renato) : II problema della coltura nella Colonia Eritrea {The Problem of Agriculture in the Colony of Erythrea). Biblioteca distu li coloniali dell'Istituto coloniale italiano (I^i- brary of Colonial Studies of the Italian Colonial Institute). Rome, cooperativa tipogratica Manuzio, 1910. SCHWEINFURTH (Prof. Gr. G.; ; II prcsente e I'avenire della colonia Eritrea {The Pusent and the Future of the Colony of £ry//jn'a). Translated by A. M. Milano. Stahilimento tipografico Bel- lini, 1894. I^ERJVi.\si {Cap. Carlo) ; Ii:hrea is fertile, and — unless there are anomalies due to atmospheric phenomena or devastation by locusts — the natives obtain abundant and varied harvests by superficial and extensive husbandry. The climate, the hydrology and the soil of Erythrea combine to create con- ditions adapted to very diverse forms of agriculture, the most numerous and productive of which could not be practised in Italy (i). (i) See in this conucction Allcgaio C. of the Relazione sulla Colonia Eriirca (1910 and 1911) bj^ F. M.\RTiNi, piesented by the minister Prinetti to the Cliambcr of Deputies during the ses- sion of 13 December 1912. (L'agricoltiira ncll'Eritrea. Report of the extraordinary civil ro3^al Commissioner bv Dr. Gino B.\rtlommei-Gioli) . 72 KRYTHkEA - AGRIClI/rUKAL ECOXOMY IX GENERAL To a brief examination of native agriculture, the distinction between agricultural zones — which is customary among the local population and ac- cepted by most botanists and explorers in Ethiopian regions — is necessar}'. The natives are used to distinguish between three great zones, the different characteristics and aspects of which are marked by their altitude and conse- quently by the distribution of their flora. They are the Quolla or Colla (Hot Land), the Uina Dega (Mountain of the \^ine) and the Dei^a (^loun- tain). The first rises from the pea-level to an altitude of about 1800 me- tres (i) and has an essentially tropical character. The chief crops cultiva- ted in it are dura, dagussa, maize, pania, sesamum and cotton. The second zone is between the altitudes of 1800 and 2400 metres. Its climate is temperate and suited to the cultivation of the cereals of Europe. The crops special to this zone are corn crops, being a mixture of munerous kinds in which predominate hard corns, barley and oats (cereals which cannot be cultivated below an altitude of 2000 metres), taff, linen and some vege- tables (beans, chick peas etc.). Dura, dagussa, maize, haricot beans and lentils are also cultivated in these two zones. The third zone lies bej'ond the altitude of 2400 metres and is little represented in the colon}'. Its agricultural aptitudes do not differ much from those found in Uina Dega but it is better adapted to the exclusive culture of corn and barle>^ If however the cUmatic- agricultural conditions of Er>'threa be consid- ered, from the point oi view of scientific agriculture, on which the colonj-'s future depends, it must be divided into six zones which we will call climatic- agricultural (2). i) Coastal and torrid zone, having rare and torrential rain. — The land adapted to agriculture is ven,^ permeable and sandy. The climate is very dry and the vegetation very rare. There is a tacit convention to call this region desert, but in reality it has the characteristics of a desert only where the land is moving T the stable land has rather the characteristics of the steppe, its vegetation consisting of thorny and gramineous plants. No European practises agriculture and natives do so to a ver}- limited extent, for ordinary agriculture is subject to too much uncertainty. It is however a mistake to think that the coastal region of the colony could not lend itself to agriculture. It has on the contrary conditions which allow of the forma- tion of numerous oases, by means of the cultivation of date-trees — which might in itself be very renuinerative — and the planting in theii shade of cereals and plants having an industrial value, such as sorghos, dura, maize, henna and the plants suited to garden cu Itivation, especially babinia — which is the authentic jute — and melokia; a valued succedeneum of jute. 2) Zone of winter rains. — Native agriculture is here habitually fairly (i) I metre = 1.094 j'aids. (2) This division follows on researches undertaken by Professor Isaia Baldrati, director of the experimental agricultural bureau of the colony of Erylhrea, the results of which have ap- peared in excellent publications. Among these is the report on this subject read to the Italian Colonial Congress of Asmara in 1905. LAXD TEXURE AND COLONIZATION ^■;^ extensive and some examples of European agriculture are not lacking. The natives confine themselves to growing maize, dura, sorgho sugar, and neuk (i) in small quantities. The Europeans on the other hand have grown sesamum and are growing tobacco with excellent results. There is one example of native vegetable gardening. Successful experiments were made with cotton in 1902, and experience seems to show that the Ameri- can varieties are to be preferred. In 1904 an attempt was made to grow Egyptian cotton but with negative results. It may be affirmed that pre- cocious cottons of the Up pi an t^pe or rustic cottons of the Texas-]\Iexico, Ab^'ssinia and India types can be profitably grown (2). The experience of the agricultural bureau has shown the possibility of cultivating with profit the arachide, the agave sisalana, the Alexandrine clover, several gramineous forage plants, taff, haricot beans of various kinds and amhrevade. On the whole this region may be considered to be peculiarly adapted to agriculture but its resources are still latent. 3) Zo7ie having two rainy seasons. — This zone is well adapted to the growth of the products which commerce calls colonial products. The coun- trj^ is much varied and still largely wooded and its altitude varies from 400 to 2000 metres. Most of its area is uncultivated and used as pasture for their flocks by nomad shepherds. Outside the ordinary pastures the natives grow cotton. This plant grows hixuriantly but is sometimes damaged by rains while it is maturing. Almost all the vallej^s of this region are con- stantly watered by the springs or by the water which circulates in the beds of torrents. The farm of the Colonial vSociety is within this zone. Almond- trees, fig-trees and vines flourish in it. It includes a coffee plantation. Indigo grows wild abundantly and in quite important quantities. The ex- perimental field of Filfil was established in this zone. As regards coffee-grow- ing, it is well to note that it is possible here, and that on the eastern slopes, sittiated at an altitude of from 900 to 1700. metres, it promises excellent results. It is indispensable that a coffee-plantation should be shaded by non-deciduous trees. If irrigation be undertaken within the first two or three 3'ears success is certain, and e^'en without irrigation the climate makes good results probable. The cinnamon tree, the sago tree and the carludovica for Panama hats also promise well, planted in excellent soil and well shaded, even if there be no irrigation. All the common crops already noticed as suited to the zone of winter rains are also certain to succeed, and dry rice, of the Manchuria and IMayotte varieties, should be added to them. India- rubber plants also promise well, especially the Ficus elastica and Cresptosiegia grandifloya. There are further groves of wild orange and lemon trees and the yam grows wild. Several grantees have already devoted themselves to coffee-growing. (i) Neuk is grown beside coni and barley and gives an oil of excellent quality which is even fit for cooking. In Europe it is known as niger. (2) In this connection see also Allegalo D. in Martini's report : Delia coltura del cotone neW Eritr ea hy \\XTe\io Paoletti, Relazioni speciali per i singoli prodotti colianiali in Atli del II . Congresso degli Italiani all'Estero, Vol. I, 2nd part ; and reports on this subject in Att-i del Con- gresso coloniale italiano in Asmara, Vol. I. etc. 74 ERYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL 4) Temperate zone having summer rains. — This zone comprises the greatest part of the land of Asmara. Saganeiti and Adi Ugri, part of the land of Cheren and a considerable part of the territory of the Habab. It is the region most densely populated, both by natives and by Eitropeans, and con - sequent!}' most widely cultivated. Fundamentally the crops are those of FAirope. Some crops are alreadj' habitually and extensiveh' cultivated — as ta-ff wheat, barley, neuk and dry vegetables. Agriculture on the high Er}-- threan plateau neglects modern rules almost entirely : work is done without method ; there is no manuring or succession of crops. It was thought that it would be very difficult to establish a succession for the crops of the high pla- teau. The difficulty lay in the choice of a crop which would renew the soil and in the lack of vegetable fodder, but to-day it has been almost comple- tely overcome. The most precocious varieties of the dura, potatoes, beans for sowing, some vegetable fodders, clover of Alexandria and lucerne grass can be used as being capable of renewing the soil. There is production not only for local consumption, biit also for export in the case of linen, .grain, neuk, colza, spices, potatoes and meal. 5) Hot zone having summer rains. — The most important and charac- teristic territory in this zone is that of Cheren. The irrigated cultivation of tropical fruits and vegetable-garden plants is here of considerable import- ance, thanks to the efforts made by Europeans and Sudanese. Ordinary native agriculture produces dura, bultuk, haricot beans, neiik and cotton. The lands of this zone might bear large crops for industrial purposes. In well formed soil the short-fibred American cottons give good results, without irrigation, even on hilly land. The arachis, the castor-oil plant, indigo and agave sisalina justify the best hopes entertained for them. Manihot gla- zovii or Ceara tobacco promises well and gives an excellent product. 6) Zone having a torrid climate. — There is little information as to the climate of this region. It seems however that usually it enjo^^s more rain than the high plateau, and moreover — since the temperature is always very high immediatel}!- after rain, its ordinary agriculture seems to be somewhat problematic. The population is little addicted to agriculture, and such as they do practise is faulty. Until a few years ago no ordinar>- agri- culturewas undertaken by Europeans. It is how^ever in this legion that the first attempts at growing cotton gave excellent results in 1902, and that moreover the Milanese firms obtained their vast grants for cotton-growing. It is however almost certain that the ctdtivation of long-fibred Egyptian cotton cannot give sure guarantees, if it be not helped by irrigation, a mat- ter which presents no great difliculties since this region has rivers (Case, vSetit, Barca and their tributaries) having running water or layers of water above their beds and subject to floods. The future of this region depends therefore almost exclusively on the construction of w^orks of irrigation which will allow its waters to serve agriculture (i). We will end this report with (i) In this connection it is important also to notice the Ca;/e speciali dei terreni coltivati e dei terreni coliivabili ma non coltivati (Special maps of cultivated lands and cultivable but un- cultivated lands) of several commissions of Erythrea, piiblished in Martini's report in 1913, Vol. IV 2nd part, established by M. Checchi, G. Giardi and A. Mori (Sheets 6 bis to 11 bis). I^ND TENURE AND COLONIZATION 75 the remark that in all Er^'threa the Indian fig-tree grows well in the regions having an altitude of from 900 to 1000 metres or more. This is truly pro- vidential for the natives, for they can feed on the fruit for several months of the year and it exists in such quantities that some years ago its utilization for the manufacture of alcohol was even contemplated. The importance of the trees for fodder is no less: they feed the live stock as well as the natives. By the means of this tree a solution of the problem of reforesting districts of Erythrea might be found or at least sought. A pohcy of forestry might be placed on the basis of a well understood association of woodland and pastureland and a scientific economy with regard to the mountain terri- tories. B. — I Ave Stock Farming. Of the different varieties of animals kept in Erythrea animals intended for meat, particularly cattle, have most interest, especially in view of their importation into Italy. Erythrea is rich in cattle ; but unfortunately breeding is often absolutely primitive, for methods of selection are almost entirely ignored and are not applied. None of the possible improvements of the primitive systems are known and they have never been adopted. It should be added that no care is taken of the pastures, that there are no artificial prairies, and that it is the custom to harvest prairie grass for hay- making. Other and graver drawbacks exist with these. Until recently and for many years, from 1887 to 1903, the live stock of Erythrea was contin- ually threatened and attacked by cattle disease. During this long pe- riod the matter was not even investigated ; nothing was done against the scourge, except that shortly before 1903 there was an attempt at serum vac- cination which however yielded neither theoretical nor practical results. It was indeed made empirically rather than scientifically. In order to find a remedy for the loss to which cattle farming was subject from epi- zoot}^, which destroyed the live stock of whole regions when it raged, vS. E. Martini, then governor, took in 1903 a wise step. He charged a special mission to look into this most delicate question. The mission identified and studied the plague, established the distinction between it and the pro- tozoic diseases with which it was confused, and laid done what were prac- tical methods of fighting and preventing it. The IstiUito siero-vaccinogeno of Asmara was then founded for the pre- paration of the necessary sera and vaccines ; men began to rely on really scientific criteria in vaccinating the beasts ; and a serious, energetic and vic- torious compaign against the terrible disease was undertaken. The bene- ficent influence — economic, sanitary and political — of vaccination was dis- seminated everj-^where. It may be afiirmed that today the plague has (i) Cf. in this connection A. Omodeo, V. Peglion, G. Valenti, La Colonia Eritrea. Rome, Bertero, 1913. volume I, section II, No. V. of the first part (Report of Professor Peglion), and in general all Professor Peglion's report which forms the second section of this volume (pp. 135-215). ERYTHKICA - AGKICI"IhTTTRAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL completely disappeared from En^threa where almost all animals of the cat- tle tribe are rendered immune against it. A corollary to the tenacious struggle was the considerable increase in the number of the cattle. According to the last census, made in 1905, there were then already 300,000 head of fully grown cattle. The results of the census of the cattle of the colony of Erythrea are found in ]Martini's report of 1913 (Vol II. Allegati No. 67, pp. 987-1000) (i), The census of 1905 supplied the following data : Camels Horses Cattle Sheep Census of 1898 . . 30,669 26,205 177,969 770,129 " 1905 . . 46,933 29,789 295,717 736,132 Difference + 16,264 + 3,584 117748 — 33 ,997 If however it be remembered that on the occasion of this last census a good third of the animals were not declared by the natives — alway averse from such declarations because they fear taxes and also perhaps because they are jealously reserved as regards their own property ; ;that these people consume no meat whatsoever ; and that in the five years after the census and until today the mortality from the plague, which once amounted to wholesale massacre rather than decimation, has ceased, because no more cases have occurred where serum vaccination is practised : if all these things be remembered it is obvious that the figure 300,000 must in reality much more than have doubled. The number of the heads of cattle must be at least 700,000, as was calculated in Erythrea in 191 1. Such number is equiva- lent to one eighth of the total number of cattle in all Italy, found to be 6,198,861 at the last census. The production of sheep and goats is no less large and increases continually. These animals numbered in 1905 nearly a million and are now reasonably computed at more than two millions. These data taken from the census of 1905 and from other and more recent information and researches — supplied by the district commissioners, the direction of civil affairs and the direction of the institute for the produc- tion of serum of Asmara — show that the number of cattle in Er\i;hrea in relation to the poj^ulation is proportionately far larger than in Italy. In Italy it is stated that there is one head of cattle for everj^ six or seven inhabitants ; whereas in Erythrea, where before the war the population was about 400,000, there were then about two heads of cattle for each inhabitant. If the number of cattle be compared to the area of Erythrea — 115,000 square kilometres — there are found to be six heads to every square kilometre, while in Italy there are 21.62 to ever^- square kilometre. (i) See also sheets XX and XXI of vol. IV. of the same rcjiort (Carte speciali) where is reported the distributon of Wealth in live stock in the dilTerent districts of the colony (Distribu- zione dclla ricchezza in bcstiame nelle varie regioni dclla colonia and Distribuzione del bestiame nelle varic regioni della colonia. LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION 77 That this figure should in Erythrea be six is the more remarkable be- cause of the vast almost desert expanses of territory included in the total area, such as the deserts of Dancalia and the lands between the Gasc and the vSetit. The export of live oxen from Erj^threa to Italy, of preserved meat in cases and of. frozen meat or meat preserved by refrigeration presents a problem not yet solved, which will certainly be studied and rightly de- termined before long. The usefulness of such an enterprise is evident, in view of the prices in force in Erythrea, where a live ox weighing three quintals (i) does not cost more on the average, than 17 Maria Theresa thalers, that is about 32s. § 3. The LAND REGIME. In order well to miderstand the bearing of the recently adopted land policy, it is necessary to show the essential lines on which Ethiopian pro- perty was organized among the populations of the high plateau at the time of the Italian occupation. In Abyssinia there is private property in land. The lands called resti are the freehold of the families of agriculturists. The etymology of the word resti implies occupation : it is derived from rassete which means " to occupy " and marks the title by which the land was acquired. The resti is not an individual property but one which belongs to a race, to a fainily : it is therefore a collective property. Its collective organization does not however cut it off from being private and absolute. It can be transmitted by inheritance and alienated by sale and purchase^ by exchange or by gift. Property in it is collective owing to the constitution of families which are today still patriarchal, and because of the method in which agriculture and shepherding are practised on it. Beasts are bred and raised in the open aii and pastures and fallow-lands there- fore remain common ; and since cereals are cultivated in turn over large zones, fields are appropriated only temporarily. Hence the custom of dis- tributing them by lot. Thus conditions are like those which Tacitus de- scribed as existing among the Germans (2) and which still subsist in the Apennines. The collective organization of private property, as determined by custom and imposed by economic needs, is not incapable of reformation but can be modified at will by those having rights in it. If therefore the transition were to be made tomorrow from the system of agricultiire now in force to intensive culture, there would be nothing to prevent the indi- vidualization of property. The form of property can be modified as has happened before, but the element which ought to subsist is that of the cultivator's free ownership. (i) I quintal = 220 lbs. (2) Arva per annos mutuant et superest ager. 78 ERYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL Besides resti there is another from of ownership, gidti. This tenure is feudal by origin and nature! the sovereign grants seigneural investiture with a certain holding to a person he favours. The gulti is therefore less repre- sentative of a right than of an office, a public charge, a delegation of the sov- ereign prerogative. The gtiUegna who has been invested with the gidti receives the tribute and pays it in whole or part to the sovereign ; he assembles and commands the armed men in war, administers justice in the first instance and declares to the sovereign the causes as to which there may have been an appeal. Therefore while resti is economic occupation and the restagna an individual who occupies for his own profit, gulti is pohtical occupation and the gultegna holds a public office. The gnltegna retains for himself a part of the tribute (a tenth) and causes part of the lands of the gidti to be culti- vated on his behalf as the appanage or salary of his post, a fact which in no way changes the nature of his occupation. The sovereign's economic right and that which be delegates to the feu- datories is chiefly the right to receive the tribute. The sovereign — the government — cannot reach the gulti except in fully determined cases. An absolute respect is thus shown to private property. These cases are those of i) the total extinction of the gultegna s line ; 2) his confiscation for rebel- lion or felony ; 3) his failure to pay tribute ; 4) his abandonment or volun- tary renunciation by permanent absence of his land. Finally we must recall that this organization of property, of which we have described the chief features, does not affect the vast regions inhabited by Mussulman and Pagan tribes, such as the districts of the Gasc, the Setit, the Barca, the Senhit, the Sahel, the Assaorta and the Dankalia, in which private property does not exist and the pastoral tribes have a customary right to pasture their animals freely on all of the territory not intended to be arable. In these districts property in the soil may really be considered to be vested in the State, so true is it that the peasants occupying lands, in order to grow cereals, have to pay a due or domainialtax which- has no re- semblance to a tribute. Without going back to the political and historical vicissitudes, which characterized the first period of the Itahan occupation of Erythrea and reached their last stage during the war against Abyssinia in iScj^-iSgG, it is well to recall, as an explanation of and a commentary on the decree of 31 January 1909 organizing land in Er>i;hrea, that in the period from II May 1893 to 12 July 1895 a series of decrees, promulgated in the colony, declared vast tracts of land to be domanial and reserved. In view of the organization of property in Er5rthrea, as this has been briefly described, it is easy to understand how profoundly these decrees, which authorized {he creation of a domain, disturbed the minds of the popula- tion of the high plateau. They contained an entirely new conception of the regulation of property, according to which the State had the right to claim lands for itself not only for objects of utiHty — a case which might within limits have been allowed b}' Abyssinian law — but also in order to appropriate these lands to colonization by white men, by the invading people. It was natural that violent confiscation, although in fact it affected only restricted LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION 79 zones, should suffice to persuade the natives that they saw the beginning of a system which httle by httle would cause them to be entirely despoiled of their property in land. On the other hand in the districts inhabited by Mussulman and Pagan tribes relatively vast territories could be subtracted from the domain held in common usufruct, for reasons already given, without seriously disturb- ing the rights or interests of the native tribes, who moreover populated these districts somewhat sparsely. The mistake in the decrees which formed a State domain was that they almost gave sanctity to the principle that a de- claration of authority is necessary in order to establish the State's superior right to lands ; whereas in Abyssinian law the sovereign or any tenant of the sovereign, that is the giiltegna, can dispose of any lands not resti. Thus these decrees limited instead of extending the State's superior power, giving rise to the belief that it concerned only lands which had been declared part of the domain. Thus this state of affairs caused in the colony much discontent which had to be eliminated if the population were to be pacified. Two measures might lead to this. A decree repeating those promulgated to form a State domain might be issued, the rights acquired by grantees being safeguarded, a serious step which might injure the government's prestige. Alternatively they might be modified so that they would become ineffective where they were held to be counter to the rights of the population and dangerous to public authority. The modification to which the colony's government had recourse was as follows. Article 14 of the law of 24 May 1903 had provided that Acts prior to this law in date should not be enforced if they had not been includ- ed in the collection of Acts of Public Authority to be issued within two years, a term afterwards prorogued so that this collection was approved only by the royal decree of 30 December 1909. In this collection thirty decrees creating the State domain were not included, because they were not thought consistent with the land organization approved by the royal decree of 31 Jan- uary 1909 or because they ran manifestly counter to the rights of the popu- lation. The decrees creating domain land which remained in force are applicable only to an area of no more than 15,500 hectares, admitting of cultivation, and to 200,000 hectares which were decreed in the first place to be attached to the State. We come thus to the royal decree of 31 January 1909 which fixed the land organization of the colony of Erythrea (i). A. — Placing of lands at the State's Full Disposal The measure of placing lands at the vState's full disposal is identified with the jurisdictory regulation of land, and was necessary to the introduc- tion of a regime of agricultural grants according to precise and definite criteria. (i) Supplement to the Bollettiiw Ufficiale ddla Colonia Eritrea, 25 July 1909, No. 28. ERYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL The jurisdictory regulation of the lands is the subject of Clause I. of the ro3'al decree o^ 31 January 1909, which establishes that propert}^ in the colony's soil belongs to the Italian State, the rights being safeguarded which belong to the native population, as well as those which may belong to third parties as the result of a title emanating from the Italian govern- ment or recognized by it (Article I). The rights of the native population to the land they enjoy in conformity with old local customs will be res- pected (Article 2). The public domain includes roads (railways and cart and caravan roads), the seashore, the ports, gulfs and beaches, military stations and fortresses, telegraph and telephone lines, and in general all property intended for public use (Article 3). The domain includes surface and subterranean watercourses, the chief dividing lines of waters and natural springs. Only a right to use the waters can be granted, and such use is alwa^^s subject to the exigencies of public interest, in the measure of the property's need. Otherwise the waters belong to the domain. No works of deflecting or gathering the waters can be executed without the government's express authorization. The colony's domain of which disposal may be made includes : a) lands which were recognized before the Italian occupation as be- longing to earlier governments ; b) lands formerly belonging to native tribes, parts of tribes, races or families now extinct ; c) lands abandoned for more than three years by the native tribes, parts of tribes, races or families to which they belonged ; d) lands in the various circumstances in which according to native custom they devolve on the State ; e) lands which reached the condition of confiscated property ; b) woods and forests ; g) mines, quarries and salt-mines ; h) lands frequented by populations practising migratory pasturage, on which however the rights to pasturage and to the waters of such popula- tions must always be respected within the limits prescribed by necessity; i) the gulti (fiefs) constituted for ofiices, individuals, families or de- termined religious organtizations, on which however the customary usufruct of fixed populations (i) must be respected within the limits prescribed by necessity ; /) in general all lands not comprised under Articles 2 and 3, those of which Article i treats being reserved. The lands of which there is question in Article 2 may be resumed bj' the State, and assigned according to circumstances to the public domain or (i) As regards tliis provision il should be noticed that if the giilti affect private- proixrly (^-^s/f) itdotsnotadrlaninchof land tothedoniain. Ifhowcvcr it affect lanels which may really be disposed of, the authority to dispose of them is inactive since all such lands, whtilur gulii or not, belong to the domain. The onlj' declaration that had to be maele was that the rights of gulti were abolished, the gultegna being thus deprived of all excuse for reclining any tithe, tribute or other feudal due LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION the alienable lands, if they are destined for public use or for an occupation enabling works in the public interest. Thisma^^ happen when it has by some means been established that military exigencies or those of the public interest render the lands necessary, when the}' are to be used to form or extend urban centres, or when they seem to be too extensive for the needs of the population using them, if the agricultural and agrarian customs of these be taken into account. In all these cases there is an equitable decision as to whether there is occasion to grant compensation. Its amount will al- ways be fixed in accordance with the value of the use of which the occupiers have been deprived. All provisions relative to these matters are made by a decree of the go- vernor of the colony, issued after the arguments of those interested have been heard. There is no appeal against such decree. Tliird parties holding rights in land, on the terms of Article i, may be expropriated for a reason of public interest, legally recognized, if a just indemnity be paid to them. A decree of the governor declares the existence of such a reason and pronounces the sentence of expropriation. When an amicable settlement with the expropriate is impossible arbiters fix the in- demnity (Article 8). The lands in question in Article 2 are burdened with the payment of a land tax which ma}" be lumped with the general tribute due from the na- tive populations. The government of the colony may grant to natives of the colony enjoA-ment of lands of the domain, in proportion to their needs and in return for the payment of an annual due. In Article ii it is stated that lands and other real estate and rights relative thereto, in whatever manner they accrue to the domain, to citizens or to strangers or. to anyone within the zone of building lands, are subject to the Italian jurisdictory regime, special provisions as to them being safe- guarded. The lands enjoyed by native po]:)ulations by the terms of Article 2 are subject to the regime created by the various customs of the localities in which they are situated. Article 13 establishes that except in the case of urban properties the creation and transmission of any right attaching to real estate are forbid- den, as between natives and others. Such are the provisions of the decree of 31 January 1909 regarding the jurisdictor\' regime of lands in Erythrea. B. — A s;ri cultural Grants. Lands accruing to the alienable domain are intended for colonization, the customs and the needs of the native populations being safeguarded. The public authority grants to a certain person the right to enjoy ceitain real estate, for a stated object and period, in accordance with the provisions of Clause III of the decree in question. Analagou.sly the rules relative to the property affect the grantee's rights in the real estate, in the absence of con- trary provision. Sz ERYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL The new organization establishes that the lands of the domain must always be alienable for the purpose of colonization, and prescribes that 2,000 hectares in the temperate zone of the high plateau be at once divided into lots in order to provide for small grants, which may be of agricultural land, of building sites, of land for industrial purposes, of mines or of land for spe- cial objects. It would take too long to examine all these t^'pes of grants We will confine ourselve to those for the purposes of agriculture and industry, which merit our attention since thej^ are within the scope of this article and are capable of most influence on the economic future of the colony. They ma}^ be said to form the pivot of the whole land regime. Grants ha\dng an agricultural object may be made : a) to Italian cul- tivators themselves directly exploiting the land granted to them; b) to Italian cultivators provided with capital and personally managing their farms ; c) to capitalists, societies of capitaHsts, legalh' constituted producers' societies or other corporate bodies recognized bj' the law and_undertaking an agricultural enterprise. Grants aiming at agriculture are of three kinds : two, corresponding to those mentioned under letters a and b, emanate *rom the governor ; the third, which corresponds to letter c from the royal power. *Those of the first kind are absolutel}' free as regards a lot having the approximate area of 25 hec- tares or one or more parts of such lot. When grants are sought within a radius of less than five kilometres of an inhabited centre the}' cannot usually com- prehend more than a quarter of a lot — 6.25 hectares. They can be granted to Italian settlers (i) who cultivate them personally and have a capital of at least 50 hras for each hectare they receive. At the end of five years they become the grantee's absolute property' if he have fidfilled all conditions im- posed on him. Grants of the second kind are made to Italian cultivators who prove that they possess a capital of 100 liras for each hectare the}' receive and who personally cultivate the land. The grant to them may not be of more than 200 hectares or for a longer period than tliirty years. It is conditional on their payment of an annual due fixed by the governor every three years. If however the grantee fulfil all terms of the contract he may after five years become absolute owner of the granted land when he has paid a sum equivalent to the capital on which such annual due would be inte- rest, at a rate previouslj' fixed by the governor. Grants of the second kind cannot be made within a radius of less than ten kilometres of the chief urban centres. While grants of the first and second kinds are made in the districts having a temperate climate, those of the third kind affect essentially lands having a torrid climate and are made to capitalists or societies of capitalists for the purposes of industrial agriculture. Usually they may not be of more than 10,000 hectares but exceptionally they may be of as much as 25,000 hec- tares. The term of the grants is fixed at ninety-nine years but they may be (i) With the minister's special aiuhorizalion grants of the first ami si-cond categories may even be made to foreigners. LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION 83 prolonged for three terms of thirty years each. I^and thus granted can never be converted into absolute property. Further special grants of pasturage for the raising of live stock are made on lands not adapted to arable farming. They are for a term of ten years and may be renewed for other ten j'-ears, and they should be re- garded as grants of the third ki^d. The government of the colony may also alienate limited extents of territory, by agreement or auction, if the intention be to cultivate them. Minute rules fix the obhgations of grantees to the administration and third parties as well as the duties of the administration. If the granted land or part thereof be not cultivated the grant lapses, totally or partially. Sub-letting is forbidden, and conditions have been de- termined for the payment of the due, the lapse and the revocation of the grant, and eventual expropriation. Grants may not be ceded to third parties without the administration's consent, and any such cession must affect all the land granted and such of its moveables and other accessories as serve the cultivation or other necessity of the property. Lands which are the subject of grants of the two first kinds and their accessories and easements may not be the object of a distraint for debts of any kind whatsoever. On such lands and their dependencies products in kind may not be pledged or sequestrated unless to pay debts contracted before the grant was made and having some connection with the grant. Provisions necessary to the nour- ishment of the grantee and his family may not however be pledged in any case before the next harvest, nor may seeds needed for the coming season. Lands the subject of grants of the two first kinds may not be burdened with mortgages. On obtaining the administration's formal authority the grantees of lands may receive agricultural loans of capital, in the form and with the pri^dleges estabHshed by the provisions in force in the kingdom of Italy, the capital to be used for useful and permanent improvements and for e.K:tra- ordinary works profitable to the granted land. Such loans may be secured by mortgages. In order that granted land may not be subdivided the organization limits the holder's power to bequeath it. All grants are exempt from payment of dues on contracts and of taxes for ten j'ears. The administration may make agricultural loans in specie to grantees of the first kind for the purchase of live stock, implements and other stock, the construction of hou.ses ond rural buildings and other useful and perma- nent improvements. The administration, or eventually the Commissariat of Emigration of Rome, may — exceptionally and when the funds assigned to colonization permit — advance the sum needed for the journey from Italy to the colony, and for implements and household necessities, to three or more adult persons of one family, fitted to cultivate granted land and desirous of a grant of the first kind, but without the necessary capital. The capital necessary to installation, to the exploitation of the land and to nouri.shment until the first harvest has been garnered is also granted. 84 ERYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL The adniinistration may promote the constitution of consortiums for the execution and maintenance of hydraulic works, works of improve- ment and works connected with roads, if these be of recognised utiht}^ to the grantees, and also for the common purchase of machines, seeds and other such articles. The administration ought to participate in the consortium as it may increase the value of neighbouring domain lands which have not yet been granted. When these works are also of general utility the administration should bear a proportionate part of the expense. When moreover it seems ne- cessary^ the administration may form obligatory consortiums, bearing not less than a fifth share of the total cost of the labour or work undertaken. The ordinance has also fixed the obligations of the government to new centres of colonization which ma^^ be formed. The seco'nd chapter of Clause III {Of Grants) is concerned with grants of land for building, the third chapter with grants for industrial objects. As regards the latter it should be noted that the governor makes spe- cial grants for the harvesting and utilization of products, whether growing wild or cultivated, which are called industrial, of land having an area not exceeding 10,000 hectares and for terms of no more than fifteen years. In other cases the grants are made by the central government. Other grants may be made by the governor b)' contracts fixed as each case presents itself, for quarries, ovens and agricultural and industrial experiments. Woods may never be the object of grants, the colonj^'s government being responsible for the sale of forest-trees and other woods according to the rules of the forest code (Chapter V. ol the same clause : Various Grants). Chapter IV. of the same clause deals at length with mining grants, winch by their nature are outside the scope of this article. Chapter VI. deals with the procedure of the application for and the de- livery of granted land. Clause IV. is concerned with the cadaster, divided into the rural cad- aster which comprises all lands accruing to the domain except those includ- ed in the regulating plans, the urban cadaster which comprises the districts included in the plans regulating building in inhabited localities, and the special cadaster in which are entered lands in determined zones or localities on which particular rights exist or which present a particular interest, and in the case of which criteria and rules other than those prescribed by the rural and urban cadasters must be followed. This important clause is subdivided into four chapters, of which the first is concerned with the institution of the cadaster, the second with its formation, the third with its publication and the fourth with its preservation. As regards the rural cadaster, which is the one most interesting to us, we would briefly notice that it is divided into three categories : a) lands of the high plateau within a radius of five kilometres of the urban centres of Asmara, Addi Ugri, Saganeiti, and other lands which the government may designate ; b) other lands within the temperate zone ; c) lands within the districts hav- ing a torrid climate. Within the lands comprised under letter a grants may LAND TENITRE AND COLONIZATION 85 not, as has been said, comprise more than 6.25 hectares, that is a quarter of a lot. It is estabhshed that a beginning is at once to be made in entering lands in the cadaster. Gradualh^ they will be divided into lots of 25 hec- tares and each lot will be divided into four parts. Lands having a torrid climate are however to be registered in the cadaster as the occasions for granting them arise, without an}' division into lots. The provisions regulating the organization of the cadaster are likewise precise. The organization is provided : a) by the cadaster's map of the col- ony, on which the various lands of interest to the cadaster are marked : b) by maps showing geographically the lands of the domain, their division into lots and their respective sections ; c) by the census table which has a volume for each map, wliile each volume has a folio for each lot comprised in its map, giving the description, value and other particulars as to such lot, and its easements and rights ; d) by a register establishing how and why a property belongs to a given owner, and any limitations of his right to dispoie of it resultant on his personal disability, whether such be due to his minority, or to a suppression or prohibition of his abihty ; e) the table giving owners which forms the general Hst of the properties. Rights in real estate and alienations of these are legally affirmed only by entry in the registers of the cadaster (Article 206). The organization provides for all the conditions modifying entries in these registers. All such entries are made by the keeper of the cadaster with whom the map is deposited and who is answerable for it. The keeper is moreover responsible for losses which may be incurred through incomplete or erroneous entries. We will not notice the temporary provisions of the ordinance, the term for which they were valid having already expired. We will merely add that the application of these rules, and of many others connected with the improvement of values in the colony and the examination of its economic resources, is entrusted to a special governmental directing body called the Direction of Colonization. § 4. Colonizing experience. In the beginning of 1907 the lands forming the subject of agricultural concessions to Europeans had a total area of 11,053 hectares. The list annexed to Number 60 of the report on the colony of Erythrea presented to parliament in 1913 (vol. II.) gives all the data relative to the various concessions, their situation and extent and the object for which they were granted. It does not include the early concessions in the plain granted before 1896 and abandoned for 3'ears by the grantees, nor .some small farms, granted temporarily and not regularized. The latter have little importance. 86 HRYTHREA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL These 11,053 hectares are divided as follows : 3,420.7204 hectares on the high plateau, populated by Abyssinians and recognized as part of the domain by a special governor's decree ; 5,339.8071 hectares in the plain, towards the sea and in the Mendri Bahari — the concessions in the plain adjoining the sea are part of the lands considered as belonging to the domain because populated by Mussulmans ; 2,292.6099 hectares in the interior of the colony in lands inhabited by Mussulman populations beyond the high plateau. If they be considered in the light of the objects for which they were granted the concessions are distributed as follows : 1 13.9051 hectares. Special grants to missions, churches, convents and small farms o* building sites, in locahties in which, according to the pro- visions earlier in force, the grant of lands for building was not allowed. 1,330.1912 hectares granted to agricultural settlers, solely or chiefly occupied with agriculture. 1,199.8869 to settlers for whom agriculture was a secondary occupation, they being chiefly occupied by a trade. 8,409.15:12 granted for purposes of industry to societies or firms hav ing capital. This category includes the concessions fulfilling an industrial object because of their extent, or because special crops are grown in them or special systems adopted for their cultivation. In the period from i November 1902 to December 1912, and according to results obtained by the Erythrean mission of A. Omodeo, V. PegHon and G. Valenti (i), 289 grants were made of a total extent of some 26,000 hectares, in which the large and sometimes indeterminate concessions for the cultivation of industrial crops were included. These concessions can be classified as follows according to their extent : Number of concessions 50 138 57 21 II 5 More than" 1000 7 l/css than 5 hectares from 5 to 25 " 25 " 50 " 50 " 200 " 200 " 500 " 500 " 1000 Total .... 289 (i) Rome, Bertero, lui 3. LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION 87 The following figures give the area of the concessions : From I November 1902 to i November 1909 — still in force: From I November 1909 to 31 December 1912 — still in force : 1st kind 2nd " Agricultural concessions of 3rd kind still in force on 31 .Deccember 191 2- (approximately) « Concessions granted from i November 1902 to 31 Dec- ember 19 1 2, revoked or renounced '. . Concessions granted for limited or expired terms . . . 8,300 hectares 471 1,061 » » 12,000 » 21,832 » 3,313 573 » 25,718 ] hectares To these concessions there should be added three grants for the ex- ploitation, the harvesting and the industrial use of products growing wild (fruits of the dtim palm-tree, castor-oil grain, indiarubber and sesamum grain). Another concession was of pasturege over an area of 300 hectares. The preceding data cannot, although taken from official documents, be considered as based on more than approximate calculations. It should also be noted that all grants are not now active, whether because grantees have failed to derive a profit, or because their recent date has not allowed the necessary steps to their occupation to be taken. From other data, taken from an authorized source, it appears that un- til September 1915 there had been 102 grants of the first and second kinds of land held in free and absolute ownership, having a total area of 3,392.0969 hectares. From an of&cial source we learn also that concessions for quarries and ovens up to the end of 1915 numbered twenty-seven. Mining concessions and permits for searches and superficial borings up to 15 April 1916 num- bered eight and the grantees included two syndicates, to one of whom were granted the goldmines of Cheren and to the other the peridot mines of the islands of Kad Ah. Finally at the end of 1916 four permits were granted to gather the fruit of the dum palm-tree in the domanial woods of Barca. * * * These results to which Itahan colonization in Erythrea has hitherto attained and the numerous studies of which they have been the subject allow the statement that this colony cannot, and never can be, an outlet 88 EKYTHREA - AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL for superfluous population. We have not space in which to examine the reasons for this statement. Some of them have however an importance shown by their mere enumeration, as for example the climate against which Europeavis contend with too much difficulty, the relative density of the population b}^ natives, and their attachment to the soil of the country. Further Erythrea is not and never will be a purely farming colon^^ for a government who understand the interests of the mother country can never desire a colony which is only agricultural since in such there is bound eventually to be an opposition of interests. Er\i:hrea should rather be utilized for economic purposes. To this end it is important that a profit should be drawn from all its various natural and social elements, and that it should be worked by Italian settlers associated with natives. Looked at in this aspect the colony of Erythrea presents total as- sets of great importance. It is the human element which, in Er\i:hrea as everywhere else, has a high value. To solve this problem in relation to the whole rural economy- of Ery- threa we must follow the advice of Marchi, who stated that not substitutes for the native, but men able to direct and make use of him, should be sought. It is on this principle that the present programme is founded RUSSIA. THE RESUI^TvS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM IN RUSSIA. PART II. § 5. lyAND ORGANIZATION ON NADIEI, LANDS. In the first part of this article (i) the organization of the enquiry, the farms as constituting its object and the twelve provinces in which it took place, were described in their general outlines. We wish now to examine more closely the results attained by the enquiry and to be able to establish the influence which the new forms of tenure and agriculture have had on the course and the development of peasant farming in Russia. The average size of those of the investigated farms which were on nadiel land was as follows in the twelve provinces : Settled Unsettled Total Nadrel l^ni s.'^BongliT^ni deciatines (.) Houtor farms in which home- stead has been moved .... 12.5 1.2 13.7 Houtor farms in which home- stead has not been moved. . 7.6 2.5 lo.i Otroub farms " 12.3 2.0 14.3 If only the settled land of the unified holdings were taken into account, these average figures would in general correspond with that which expresses the average area of the farms settled on nadiel land in all the forty-seven governments of European Russia in which the agrarian reform has been carried out, namely 10 deciatines [1,252,020 peasants' farms having a total area of 12,553,046 deciatines (3)]. The average area of peasant holdings (i) International Review of Agricultural Economics, December 1916. (2) I deciatine = 2 acres 2 roods 31.9555 poles. (3) OT'^eTHbiH cB'hjxhnia o lafharejii-noeTn SeM-ieycTpoHTCubHuxi. KoMMncitt Ha I HHsapjl 1915 r. {Memorial on the Activity of the Land Readjustment Commission up to I January 1916). Published by the Department for the Tenure of State lyand, 1915- 90 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IK GENERAL varies very notably in different provinces, from 3.1 deciatines in Krement- schug province (Government of Pultava) to 41.1 deciatines in Nikola] evsk province (Government of Samara). Unification and the rendering contiguous of the parts of holdings has distinctly improved the condition of the land and the method of employing it, in comparison with the time before the land settlement. The fact that the land was so much cut up into parcels and that the parcels were scattered over the whole of the communal property, together with the distance at which they lay from the homesteads, often made it impossible, because luiremunerative, to cultivate the strips which were furthest re- moved in spite of the very noticeable scarcity of land. After the land read- justment there was an unmistakable and total change in the position, a point which we illustrate in the following table. THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 91 The Distribution and Relative Distances of the Parcels of Holdings of Nadiel Land in the Different Provinces before and at the Time of the Settlement. Farmers of nadiel land. a = before the settlement 1 6 = at the time i of settlement | in all the provinces HaviiiE strip of land 2 3 4-5 6-10 11-20 21-40 41-60 61-100 more than 100 strips of land. Nadiel farmers having the furthest removed strip at a distance from the homestead of 0.0 versts (i) lip to 0.25 0.25 to 0.5 0.5 .. i.o I » 3 3 " 5 More than 5 » Houtor farmers having the furthest removed strip at a distance from the homestead of 0.0 versts up to 0.25 n from 0.25 to 0.5 versts ' 0.5 » 1.0 » I » 3 » 3 " 5 » More than 5 versts 553 3,751 299 6,931 538 2,515 2,061 908 3,810 78 2,863 a I) 973 a 622 b — a 212 b — a 235 b 3,715 a 108 b 776 a 596 b 1,062 a 2,089 b 1,513 a 4,093 b 2,980 a 1,785 b 1,731 a 5,177 b 2,406 a 22 b 2,505 a 28 b 109 a 223 b r84 a 891 b 301 a 1,697 b «. 301 a 286 b 59 a 733 b 121 fil I verst = 1166.^^2 yards. 92 RUSSIA - AeRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL This table gives us a deep insight into the whole agrarian revolution which is being accorhplished in European Russia. Of the 14,183 farms on nadiel territory investigated the land was before the settlement held in one strip in onty 553 (3.9 per cent.) ; and in 2,898 (20.4 per cent.) was divided into from two to five strips. The land of the other farms was scattered in six, twenty, forty or even more than a hundred strips. This parcelling of the land of a holding was especially marked in the provinces of Ostrov (Government of Pskov), Sitschevka (Government of Smolensk) and in Mo- loga (Government of Jaroslav), where farms having less then eleven separ- ate parcels of land were not be met with at all. Of the whole number of the farms investigated scientific agriculture was in consequence possible only in 24.3 per cent. After the settlement not a single farm remained which included more than ten separate parcels of land, and even such num- ber was foimd only in few (0.6 per cent.) ; in 3,751 farms (26.4 per cent.) the land had been united into one piece to form houtor farms ; in 48.9 per cent, of the whole number it had come to be divided into two ; and in 17.7 per cent, into three pieces. It is to be noted moreover that the site of the homestead was reckoned as a separate piece. If this circumstance be taken into account it appears that almost half the total number of farms had had their land unified into one piece. If to these the houtor farms be added, 75.3 per cent, of the total number are found to have had their lands made contig- uous. The chief evil of the conditions of peasant farming, the great par- celling of the land and the extent to which the parcels were scattered, has been if not entirely removed yet much reduced. Certain rights, such as those in woodland, meadows and gardens, have not come within the scope of the unifying process because the}^ have a par- ticular value distinct from average values. Therefore it has been necess- ary to deliver land divided into from four to five parcels to 6.4 per cent, of the farms. There were also lands unfit to be tilled which could be used only for herding cattle. Such lands, which formed 10 per cent, of the whole area settled, were left as common meadows. This was the more ne- cessary because at the beginning of the settlement the questions of fodder and of the use of grass pasture were not settled, and therefore a sharp break in the tenure of the huts standing on the summer meadows, which hitherto had been common property, was to be avoided if possible. Many peasants before the time of the enquiry of 1913 bought new land in addi- tion to that awarded to them under the settlement, to which they thus added a second piece. The unification of such bought land with the nadiel land was first made possible by the law of 29 May (11 June) 1911 which had force from 15 (28) October. The bought land was until 1911 so regulated that it could not be used for the farms formed up to that date. This partly explains why in 21 per cent, of the houtor and otroub farms investigated there were altogether, besides the settled land, 26,863 deciatines not in- cluded in the unified farm land. As regarded the remoteness of the peasants' lands from their home- steads remarkable results were, as appears from the table, also attained ; THE RESUI,TS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 93 but this evil can be entirely cured only when the site of the homestead is removed to the otrouh. After the settlement 1,292 peasants (7.4 per cent.) (i) sold the entire holdings of nadiel land allotted to them, and 1,121 (6.4 per cent.) sold part thereof, such sales including altogether 2,413 farms having a total area of 18,766 deciatines. Among the caiises for these sales is the circumstance that many peasants live outside their farms, being occupied as employees or labourers, and have long since lost all connection with the land ; and that for others their holdings had become too small and they sold them in order to emigrate to Siberia or to buy larger holdings from the Land Bank or the crown. The nun of some farms, whether as a result of bad harvests, cattle disease, the lack of labour in a family or other cause, was also instru- mentat in bringing about sales. The average price of the land uas raised by almost 50 per cent, after the settlement. In Siberia and European Russia 22,022 deciatines were bought b^^ the peasants after the settlement, that is more than the 18,766 deciatines which they sold. This is proof that the economic basis of the newly formed peas- ants' farms is firm and solid, and that even in the initiatory period, when farming had to be fundamental^ reorganized, most of the peasants were able to increase the area and importance of their farms by buying land. The number of farmers who took land on lease after the settlement increased in all the provinces except Mologa. The average area of leasehold land belong- ing to a farm decreased however ; and so did also the number of lessees, even considered in relation to the decline of the average area of leasehold land. Rents rose very notably after the settlement. The question of the subdivision of farms among heirs received very particular attention at the enquir3^ The number of farms thus subdivided — 323 (2.2 per cent.) — was small and 752 farms had been formed from them. The position of these resultant farms was in general not prosperous. In order to provide in the future against the formation of such economically weak and unpro- fitable peasants' farms the Chief Office of L,and Organization and Agricul- ture has placed before the Duma a scheme for a law, entitled " Measures for I^essening the Subdivision of the lyands of Small Farms formed with State Aid ". § 6. IvAND SETTLEMENT ON THE LANDS OF THE PEASANTS' LAND BANK AND ON CROWN LANDS. I/and settlement is generally far easier on lands acquired from the Peas- ants' Ivand Bank or the crown than on nadiel land. In the case of the former it is not necessar\', as in the work of unifying strips of land of differing values on nadiel land, to give when measuring and allotting any attention to the present and past interests of the villagers. Onty considerations of a tech- nical kind have to be taken into account when the crown and bank laud are (i) Eight farms which arose as a consequence of subdivision by inheritance are included. 94 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL allotted — as that of contriving such a favourable division of the houtor and otroub farms as will bring them nearest to a square form, and of providing a water supply and rights of way. A valuation is undertaken in this case with a view to establishing only the selling price ; and land settlement can therefore be brought to a more advanced stage of completeness. The enquiry covered, as has already been said, 4,832 farms on bank and crown lands, 2,566 of them being settlements on hoiitor and otroub land and 2,276 otroub farms of which the owners had remained on their nadiel lands. This property was taken over from the peasants by the fol- lowing stages. Year of taking land over 1907-08 1909 191 1 Total J Number of farms i.ogo 1,851 1,460 431 Percentage of their whole number I 22.6 38.3 30.2 8.9 4.832 100 Thus at the time of the enquiry nearly 90 per cent. (22.6 -|- 38.3 + 30.2) of all farms had enjoyed the new conditions for more than three years, and almost 60.6 (22.6 + 38.3) for four years and more. The farms alto- gether comprised 77.7 per cent, of arable land, 6.4 per cent, of meadowland and 15.9 per cent, of land otherwise employed. Holders to the number of 3,373, or 69.8 per cent, of the whole number, were allotted land held in one piece; 1,377 "^^ 28.5 per cent, received land divided into two pieces, and 82 or 1.7 per cent, land divided into three or more pieces (i). Thus in settling these properties it was not alwa3^s found pos- sible to give all the peasants land iield in one piece ; for the existing division of woods and meadows necessitaxed sometimes the allotment of a second or a third strip to a farm. In addition 37 per cent, of the peasant buyers received a common meadow which comprised 11. 7 per cent, of the land bought. The average size of the bought pieces of land was 20 deciatines, their area varying from 8.3 deciatines in Bogoduchov province to 29.4 deciatines in Nikolajevsk. These farms are thus twice as large as those on nadiel land, a fact which must of course be carefully kept in mind if a comparison between the farms of the two classes be made. The area of the leaseholds of farmers was equivalent to 32.3 per cent, of their holdings of crown and bank lands, and therefore stood to these in much the same proportion as did the leaseholds of the other peasant holders to their nadiel land, the percentage in the latter case being 34.7 per cent. (29.6 per cent, before the land settlement). Even in a province so rich iu land as Nikolajevsk, where the average holding attached to a homestead is (i) The site of the homestead was when separated from the land of the settlement reckoned as a separate strip. THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 95 of 2g.4 deciatines. there are leaseholds. The circumstance cannot be ascribed to scarcity- of land but to the cause which has given rise to lease- holds on nadiel lands, namely the endeavour of the peasants to enlarge their farms, to extend their property. § 7. Financial support of the peasants under the land settlement. When the land was settled money was assured to the peasants, both for removing their farm buildings and for carrying out the simple improve- ments prescribed, in the form either of a loan or a gift. The amounts of the sums thus expended on the farms on nadiel land and on bank and State domains within each province are shown in the following table : Financial Sttpport given to the Population when the Land was Settled. a) On Nadiel Land. Total for all prov. No. of farmers moving their homesteads 3,781 They received from Credit of the Land Settlement: _ i No 1,522 I Amoimt in roubles (i) 165,944 Gifts * "^^ ^4° ' Amount in roubles 8,177 No. of farmers not moving their homesteads 11,154 They received from the Credit of the Land Settlement : Loans ^ ^° 9°^ \ Amount in roubles. 81,022 Gifts • ^°" • • •' ^^2 / Amount in roubles 5, 861 b) On Lands of the Bank and State Domains. To those moving their homesteads the Land Settlement Credit paid: Loans 1,805 Gifts 149 To those not moving their homesteads the Land Settlement Credit paid: Loans 94 Gifts - 3 Total of: Loans in roubles 231,288 Gifts in roubles 9,097 (i) I rouble of 100 kopecks ^ about 2s. i l^rf. at par. 90 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECOXOMY IN GENERAL As this table shows, the peasants who had bought lands from the Peas- ants' Land Bank or the administration of the State domains were more generously supported with money than those on the nadiel land ; but on the other hand the former were obliged when they took over their lots to pay in advance out of their own means lo per cent, of the purchase price, and 15 per cent, of them were in consequence left destitute of possess- ions and therefore much in need of help. On the whole financial support was extended to a relatively small number of the peasants and the number of gifts made was too trifling. The average sum of money received was 105 roubles a homestead, against which must be set the average cost of moving a homestead, setting up buildings and carr3dng out improvements, namely 238 roubles a homestead. Thus the giving of financial support was in no sense a philanthropic enterprise and could not act as a bait to the peasants to fall in with the reforms of the Land Readjustment Cominission. § 8. The economic position of the new peasants' holdings in severalty. In order to understand the economic position of the new farms held in severalty the investigators of these made a great point of establishing, by searching questions and tests, the value of the improvements made by the peasants on their holdings after the settlement, and that of their build- ings, their cattle and all their possessions. A comparison thus became possible between the position of the farms before and after the settlement. It has appeared in general that in the farms situated on lands of the Land Bank and the State domains the value of improvements, buildings and live and other stock is, in comparison with that existing before the land settle- ment — that is before the pieces of land were bought — distinctly higher than itisinthecaseof the farms in severalty on wrff/?>/ land. This is not surpris- ing since we know that the farms of the first category are twice as large as those of the second (§ 6) , and are moreover of earlier origin and held on a peculiar basis. A comparison of the economic positions of the two kinds of farms is possible only under reservation, and should be made not as between farms but as between areas. a) Improvements and Buildings. With the remodelhng of farms and tenures and the settlement of the land, what may be called the psychological relation of the peasant to his holding alters. The awakened sense of ownership gives rise to the wish to employ the land economicallj'- and make the smallest plot as productive as possible. Marshes are drained, stony soil is rendered tillable, land over- grown with bushes is cleared. Although when the enquiry was made most of the farms had enjoyed the new conditions only for from three to four years, more than a third of the farmers in severalty of nadiel land, 75 per cent. THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 97 of them being hontor farmers, had made most important improvements. The vakie of these was placed at 288,057 roubles, an average of 47 roubles 33 kopecks a farm, the average in the different districts varying from ii roubles 74 kopecks (Krementschug) to 140 roubles 70 kopecks (Nikolajevsk). The average area on which improvements have been made by houtor farmers is larger by 44.1 per cent, than that which otroiih farmers have improved. On the lands of the bank and the State domains expenditure on improve- ments after the purchase of the land was ten times greater than it had been in the case of the earlier holders. The average expenditure on improvements on a farm, as well as the number of farmers undertaking improvements, were on these properties larger than the corresponding averages for nadiel lands. As regards buildings, not only the number of dwellings but also that of stables, byres and barns has grown ; and this, as the report adds, points to the conclusion that the number of houtor farms grew even after the settle- ment, because the otrouh farmers ren'f&ved their farm building from the vil- lage area to their newly settled lots. The number of farmers having no farm buildings has been almost halved : it has sunk from 404 to 210. The value of the buildings rose on the investigated farms on nadiel land from 7,398,449 roubles to 9,224,963 roubles, that is by 1,826,514 roubles or 24.6 per cent. ; on the farms on lands of the Peasants' I^and Bank and the State domains — according to the estimate of the possessors themselves — from 2,136,159 roubles to 3,098,866 roubles, that is by 962,707 roubles or 45.1 per cent. b) Live and Other Stock. Before the settlement the land was so spUt up that the employment of modern agricultural machinery was not only economical!}^ unprofitable but also technically impossible. This condition altered rapidly after the strips of land had been united, and the change from the three-field system to that of intensive agriculture accomplished. The primitive implements — the plough-hatchets, the wooden harrows — have been superseded ; new ma- chines have been bought to an important extent, such as sowing, mowing, winnowing and threshing machines. This is especially the case in houtor farmS; on some of which the value of all the stock other than live stock is double what it was originally. The employment of agricultural machines has been extended by the depots of zem.stvos and the government as well as b}' private owners. The corn-winnowing and sorting machines have espe- cially increased in number in the north and north west provinces; the sowing, mowing and hay-harvesting machines in those of the south and south east. The total value of the stock other than live stock rose in the 17,567 farms on nadiel land from 836,642 roubles to 1,174,327 roubles, that is by 40.4 per cent.; in the farms on lands of the bank and the State domains it rose from 382,584 roubles to 779,558 roubles, that is it was nearly doubled. The live stock increased absolutely on all the farms investigated, if they be taken together, but not in the same measure as the other stock. As regards gS RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL live stock the proportionate increase or decrease differs very much in the two classes of farms : on the lands of the Peasants' I,and Bank and the State domains, where the newly bought land had to be cultivated, the number of animals increased throughout on every farm ; but in the farms on nadiel land, especially in the first years, the average number for each farm was shght- ly diminished. The number of the horses was reduced from 24,507 to 23,589, that is by 3.7 per cent ; that of the cows from 21,845 to 21,607, that is by I.I per cent.; and the number of the sheep from 46,720 to 30,384, that is by 35 per cent. The diminution of live stock is to be ascribed to the fact that when re- movals took place, more or less spontaneously, to the self-contained farms held in severaltj^ the earlier common meadows were in most cases done away with, and the stall-feeding of live stock is as yet not practised to a compensatory extent. The state of affairs is to be regarded however as only transitory ; for as soon as all the elements existing in a farm have been adjusted to the new factors affecting them, an increase in the number of live stock occurs. This is noticeably so in the case of sheep, as to which to accept the statement that in the new conditions of peasant farming their number dwindles would be unjustifiable or at least premature. The inves- tigations made at the Pultava experimental station have discovered, in this connection, that sheep herded on meadows and fed in stalls are almost equally profitable, and that the reduction in the number of sheep is transi- tory. At the beginning of the land settlement, when farms were being reorganized, the keeping of sheep diminished owing to the lack of meadows ; but as the farm adjusted itself to the new conditions sheep, pasturing near the homestead and fed at night with some summer grass and grass of the steppes, appeared again (i). As regards cattle generally the decrease in their number is throughout very small, especially if a calculation be based on a given area of land in- stead of a single farm. It is then discovered than on every 100 deciatines of all the land, whether newly settled or not, the following average number of live stock is found. Young Horses Cows stock Pigs In i^ixms, on nadiel Idind 11. 7 10.7 7.1 13. i » )) » bank » & State domains 11. 3 7.6 57 6.9 It appears thus that, when the calculation is made for a given area, the nadiel farms, although generally only half as large as those on bank lands and State domains, are more richly pro\'ided with five stock. This relation between the two classes of farms is particularly clear when the amount of livestock held on farms of the two categories in single provinces is compared,. as in the following tables. (i) Review of Agtarian Assistance given in the Districts of the Land Organization in the Govern- ment of Pultava in 1914. Pubishcd by the Government Zemstvos of l*iiltava, 1915. p. 45. THE RESUI.TS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 99 Farms on Nadiel Land. Average area of investigated farms in deciatines On loo deciatines Draught horses Cows Young Stock Pigs 1. Nikolajevsk 2. Krasnoufimsk .... 3. Berdjansk 4. Ostrov 5. Rschev 6. Trokki 7. Sitschevka 8. Mologa 9. Orel 10. Bogoduchov 11. Krementschug .... Average 48.2 23.2 16.5 14.7 13-8 11.7 II 3 10.7 8.4 7.8 5-9 13.8 6.1 11.8 15 11.7 3-5 9.3 7-4 21.8 14.1 18.3 12.7 12.9 II-3 II. 2 12.6 2-3 6.5 4.8 8.0 6.3 I3-I 6.6 6.8 6-5 9-9 12.7 10.7 7-1 2.5 4-7 5-6 11.7 7.8 37-2 10.7 4-3 9.3 18.9 18.4 I3-I Farms on Lands of the Agrarian Bank and State Domains. 1. Nikolajevsk 2. Krasnoufimsk 3. Ostrov 4. Berdjansk 5. Mologa 6. Orel 7. Jepifany 8. Krementschug 9. Bogoduchov . Average . . 38.2 3I-I 22.4 21.7 20.0 15-7 15-3 12.3 II-3 21.9 11.7 8.2 6.7 12.0 6.7 12.8 14.2 10.7 19-5 "•3 5-2 6.6 15-5 5-6 12.7 8.9 7-7 9.7 10.8 7.6 4.1 4.6 7-4 3-3 6.7 6.6 6.5 10.4 9.4 5-7 4.2 3-4 8.9 7-4 8.4 102 8.6 144 16.6 6.9 If these two tables be compared it appears that the average number of cattle kept per 100 deciatines is in most provinces rather higher on nadiel farms then on those on bank and crown lands. In four provinces — Mologa, lOO RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAIv ECONOMY IN GENERAL Ostrov, Rschev and Trokki — the number of cows per lOO deciatines is higher in both classes of farms than that of horses, a circumstance closely connected with the whole method of farming in these provinces, namely with the improved field system, especially with a view to Uve stock and dairy farming, and with the more extensive cultivation of grass for fodder. In the other provinces however corn growing prevails and this naturally causes draught animals to have most importance among the live stock. For the rest, in every province in which owing to bad harvests or general causes there has been a reduction of live-stock, such reduction is relatively least noticeable in the newly formed farms held in severalty, which circumstance is a clear sign of the staying power of these and their fitness to bear burdens. § 9. Agricultural assistance and the extension of co-operation. Agricultural assistance was afforded to the newly formed farms in the provinces of Ostrov, Sitschevka, Mologa, Orel, Berdjansk and Krementschug by the zemstvos ; in the provinces of Trokki, Rschev, Jepif any, Bogoduchov and Krasnoufinisk by the government ; and in that of Nikolajevsk by the zemstvo and the government. At first the help given took such forms as demonstrations, adapted to needs ; and instruction given to the peasants by means of the organization of model farms and experimental cultures; the foundation of stations for cleaning seeds, warehouses for machines and stud farms ; the holding of lectures and courses, and the arrangement of cattle shows. It was sought to provide the peasants with the knowledge necessary to farming. I^ater, as the staff of agriculturists increased, it became possible to undertake individual instruction, to know the peculiar- ities of every single farm and direct it to that path by which it could secure technical advantages and be economically profitable. Out of the system of provincial agricultural assistance arose the so called Zevier agricultural organization, which very much narrows the activities of the province and therefore gives more attention to single farms. If hitherto corn growing had dominated among forms of agriculture and had been the general ob- ject of farming, so that the prosperity of peasant farmers depended on a sin- gle factor, it was the task of the organization of the local experts to introduce other forms of agriculture, so that the peasants' income might depend vipon several factors, and when one of these failed the^^ might derive compen- sation from another. The type and the amount of expert help afforded in the twelve districts investigated appears from the following table : THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM lOI bb 0<) c fl 6(1 1 ci a S ° .2 b ;_ 4-* CI CQ O CO 1 Sfi ^ S tn a _ o « a^ S 5 ^ 5 M >4 Si ■M m c u O s sj o 0 2o M H a 1-1 .2 « M tn tn C-I tn 8 O m ■+ to M M DC PI — -v^^ M 8 -o •2 -g -3 -a 1 CO O „ O t^ m !>. O C) N t^ d V o ro t^ in M fO on M ^ in CO "3 S .3 o m o = 1 •^ r^ U-) C^ lO o CO o o o> O ON d «5 lO " VO " M Oi f-< -^ "S a 1 i « 1 '^ ON c^ vO o m o 00 N o o 0 vO d iz; >o t^ O to o vD o t-4 r^ l^ tn M M^ C-l o. in r- • IN 0) IN C-) ■s •s 2 "2 3 t^ N 1 o >o 1 •*■ O 1 I 1 t^ d S 3 M ^ 1 M ^ 1 ro M 1 1 1 00 ^ o CM o •3 *i ^ o a\ 00 o m a^ m M in ON N o o d K 5^ a '- Tf M »-l M % S ^i -S fa ►-' s >— t tn 1 — •*-• A O )H -tJ o vO 1 vO r>- in M M in to H 1 sS "to & w 1 H 1 o tf) ^ -2 5 o. 1 M c< N 1 ^ CI 1 N -li- fO H 1 i 1 1 -/J M W ? *fc- s « o •= s >o 00 M OO t^ in in ro in "-) m ro d D o- Z a w - o tn s •g 4 cd ^ ^ tn > H in tn o >^, 3 a; > h § 3 c 0 c iJ cfl !§* 1 tn o CI 'St c a 1 pq O M 'a 1—) 2 s O 1 o p2 o M ci CO ■i- in o ts. od c^, d M M N 102 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL As the table shows, the organization of the local agricultural experts was of much later origin than the settlement of the self-contained peasants' farms. This organization extends its support not only to the newh' formed farms but also to all farms within its circle of activit}', and its help thus reaches the whole rural population. For this reason the whole number of newly formed farms which at the time of the enquiry had had support from the agricultural experts, in the form of advice or UKDre practically, was not large, as appears from the following table : The Absolute and Relative Number of the Neuiy Formed Farms on which the Local Agricultural Experts gave Instruction. Name of Province Total Number of Investigated Farms except those as to which facts were incomplete Number of these Farms as to which the Experts advised Percentage of whole Number of Farms 1. Berdjansk 2. Bogoduchov ..... 3. Jepifany. 4. Krasnoutimsk .... 5. Krementschus .... 6. Mologa 7. Nikola] evsk ..... 8. Orel. 9. Ostrov. 10. Rschev 11. Sitschevka. 12. Trokki Total 1,691 3,658 1,509 1,314 2.137 337 1,891 1,095 1,335 658 1,373 2,769 19,767 225 639 971 618 974 228 426 638 400 3" 248 1,137 6,8l; 13-3 17-5 643 47.0 45.6 67.7 22.5 58.3 30.0 47-3 18.1 41. 1 34-5 Thus onh^ 34.5 per cent, of the newly formed farms have been able to draw profit from the organization of local experts ; all the others were directed to the common measures undertaken in the interest of all the rural population — the model farms, the experimental cultures and the others. The organization has been universall}- valuable to the rural districts, and has much promoted co-operation, in the form of agricultural co-operative societies, dair^^ co-operative credit societies, consumers' unions and so forth. The number of peasant farmers adhering to co- operative unions rose ver\^ notably after the land settlement, especially in the case of agricultural societies, for the members of these who were houtor and otroub farmers was almost multiplied by five. THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 10' The following table shows the development of these relations before and at the time of the enquiry-, and on nadiel lands and lands of the bank and the domains. Number of Farmer Members of Co-operative Unions All Co-operative Unions | Co-operative Credit Unions | Agricultural Societies Other Co-operative Unions \ Date of fact (i) On Nadiel Land On Lands of the Bank and State Domains a b 2,677 6.291 561 2,665 a h 2,520 6,023 540 2,610 a h 95 464 29 a b 349 23 108 § 10. Agriculture in the newly formed peasants' farms. The agrarian reform has freed peasant farming from the fetters of the ohstschina of the common land. The Fliirzwang and its consequences — simultaneous preparation of the soil, sowing, harvesting and other operations on the part of all holders — no longer limit peasant farming, which has come to develop more freely and to use fully all the available land and labour. This process of adjusting the newly settled peasants' farms to natural and agricultural factors is now in full swing but has of course not yet come to an end in its most important respects. Yet already at the time of the enquiry the following general conclusions could be made as to agriculture. The three-field system, formerly universally prevalent, no longer dom- inates agriculture but begins to give place to other and more perfect sys- tems. In the north western district the change is in the direction of a production of the raw materials of manufacture, flax being the most import- ant crop and one which can be well marketed. Rschev is an example of a district in which the three-field is being exchanged for a six-field system, the following being the order of succession : (i) fallow land is manured ; (i) a = before the enquiry; 6 = at the time of the enquiry. 104 RUSSIA - AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL (2) rye crop followed by sowing of clover; (3) clover of the first year; (4) clover of the second year ; (5) flax, and (6) oats. If the market for flax be good, flax also forms the sixth crop. This system reduces by half the extent of land which lies fallow under the three-field system, and moreover two divisio'ns are planted with fodder grasses (clover) which, as is well known, enrich the soil with nitrogen. In other districts — as in Krasnoufimsk, Orel and to some extent in Jepif any — the improvement of agriculture is directed princi- pally towards growing fodder grasses. A whole series of transitory systems, intervening between three-field and more-field farming, is to be met with everywhere. As yet they have not crystallized but they have broken away from the rigidity of three-field farming. In the southern districts, remarkable for black earth, wheat grow- ing outweighs all other forms of agriculture. The fertility of the soil makes manuring almost superfluous. The improvement in agriculture has here especially affected the technique of farming : fields are ploughed more often, stubble is turned, sowing is done by machinerj^ fallow land, whether black earth, virgin or previously ctdtivated soil, is brought under cultivation, and so forth. This leads too to retention of humidity in the soil, a matter which in the south is very important. New crops are also planted, as vetch, clo- ver, lucerne grass. The three-field system thus loses ground of necessit5^ In the district of Bogoduchov, for example, under the influence of the model fields, the following four-field system has been introduced : (i) virgin, clean and manured fallow land sown with vetch as situation allows ; (2) winter rye slowly replaced by winter wheat ; (3) millet, buck-wheat, potatoes, beet- root or beans, that is plants requiring a medium amount of labour ; (4) summer barley. The crops on the third of these divisions —the hoed crops — take up on an average 12 per cent, of the whole cultivated area, on hou- tor farms 18 per cent. On farms on nadiel land the transition to better agricultural systems is on the whole more marked than on those on lands of the Peasants' Agrarian Bank and the crown. That the better methods of distributing crops and employing the soil have already had good results, and that the yield of the newh' settled peasants' farms has largely increased, appear from the following table, in which comparisons are made in the case of crops of six kinds for the years 191 2 and 191 3. THE RESUI,TS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 105 The Yields in the Chief Grain Crops and Potatoes. Average yield of deciatine in puds (i) 1912 1913 / Nadiel farms 54.0 54.4 j^ \ Bank lands 66.5 65.6 . J lyands of village communities. . . 50.1 51.2 ' lyands of estate holders 58.9 63.6 f Nadiel farms 54.4 82.6 Winter Wheat 1 Bank lands ; • • • 45-2 73-0 J I^ands of village communities. . . 62.6 63.3 \ I^ands of estate holders 65.9 78.9 . Nadiel farms 49.8 55.6 c, „,, . \ Bank lands 57.6 61.8 Summer Wheat . ,. , r -n -.l- i Lands 01 village communities. . . 41.0 51.0 ' Land of estate holders 41.6 47.6 / Nadiel farms . 68,1 72.8 Oats ' ^^^ ^^^^^ 77-6 75-6 i Lands of village communities. . . 55.9 59.9 \ Lands of estate holders 60.1 69.3 / Nadiel farms 65.9 66.1 Barley ) ^^"^^ ^^^^^ • • • • ^7-5 734 ] Lands of village communities. . . 53.7 60.4 ' Lands of estate holders 59.0 68.1 / Nadiel farms 623.4 570.1 Potatoes ' ^^''^ ^"""^^ 5514 440-9 ' • ' • j i^ands of village communities. . . 451.8 421.0 V Lands of estate holders . . . . , 451.8 570.6 That the average yield of the lands of the Land Bank and the crown is somewhat higher than that of the nadiel lands is to be explained by the fact that most of the investigated farms on lands of the former categorj' lie in the black earth area, and are moreover of earlier foundation, while their soil has been less exhausted by tillage and farming than that of those on nadiel land. In general the differences in yield are not very important, for in the course of so short a period as three or four years the yieding capa- city of the soil on the newly settled peasant farms could not be fundamen- tally altered. It is however a great gain if it can be established that within this short period the yielding capacity of the self-contained farms held in severalty has surpassed that of the land still held by the peasants in common. (i) I pud = 40 lbs. I06 RUSSIA - AGRICUI.TUKAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL CONCLUSIONT. The conclusions as to wliich the enquiry into the unified peasants' farms has led are chiefly the following : (i) More than three quarters of the investigated farms on nadiel land received their parcels of land (the site of the homestead being left out of account) in a single self-contained piece after the land settlement. On the other hand before the settlement more than three quarters of the farms had their land distributed in at least six strips, and generally in thirty, forty, or even a hundred. (2) Half the peasant farmers have been allotted nadiel lands distant by hardly a verst from their homesteads. But before the laud settle- ment three quarters of them held land more than a verst distant from their homesteads, and a third of them land five versts or more thence distant. (3) The land settlement was most advantageous to the average peas- ants' farms, those to which small or medium-sized holdings attached. The extent of land provided for the newly settled nadiel farms was approxim- ately equal to that locally normal, except in two districts where it was more extensive and in three where it v/as noticeably less so. In general otroub farmers are somewhat better provided with land than houtor farmers. (4) Of the 7.7 per cent, of the farmers who had given up their farms on the newly settled land, 5.1 per cent, were those who, instead of the land the3' sold, had acquired a larger piece from the Peasants' I/and Bank, the crown or private owners ; others had emigrated to Siberia, and others had made the chief part of their income as employees or traders. Only 2.3 per cent, sold the land allotted to them without having, at the time of the enquiry, bought other land or provided for themselves by some trade. (5) Of the newly settled farms 2.2 per cent, were subdivided among members of families, as the result of inheritance, after the settlement. (6) ]\Iore than 40 per cent, of the peasants have carried out on their lands improvements of which the average value is 53 roubles a farm (about 47 roubles on farms on nadiel lands and some 70 roubles on those on bank lands) . (7) After the land settlement the total value of the buildings and the possessions on the newly formed peasants' farms rose b}^ 27.7 per cent. (8) About a fourth of the farmers were helped bj^ the crown after the settlement with money. Of them 2.3 per cent, had the money granted to them without obligation to repay it. The average amount of the grant was 105 roubles a farm, or 44 per cent, of the average cost of removing build- ings to new sites and carrying out improvements. (9) The number of the peasants who became members of co-operative unions was, after the settlement, more than doubled among the otroub farm- ers and quadrupled among the houtor farmers. (10) The number of farms on which fodder was grown and a success- ion of crops maintained over several years was quadrupled after the land settlement. , THE RESULTS OF THE NEW AGRARIAN REFORM 'TO7 (11) The harvest yield in 1912 and 1913 was in the oven\'helming majority of cases higher on the newly settled farms than on those still in common ownership, and still burdened with the system by which a hold- ing was made up of scattered parcels. Not infrequently it was higher on the newly settled farms than on the estates of private owners. We repeat that when these results are considered it should always be borne in mind that the newly formed peasants' self-contained farms, enjoying conditions created by the land settlement, had at the time of the en(|uiry existed onl}' for three or four years. Their reorganization, the re- modelling of all farming on them, had only just begun ; and it had been ne- cessary for the farmers to spend much time, labour and money in order to make them fit for agricultural operations a§ quickly as possible. As regards production the first years were of course the least fruitful : they were the least fa\'ourable period in the existence of the farms. And although agronomic enterprise on the part of both the government and the zemstvos helped the peasants in their farming, both with advice and more practical^, the peasants nevertheless, since help of this kind became available comparatively late, depended most on themselves and on their own experience and initiative. I^'inal conclusions could not therefore be made as to the position of the farms : the enquiry could only indicate their possible developments and establish their tendencies. For these ends the available material was sufficiently enlightening. It showed that almost all the investigated farms have happily survived the critical period of reorganization and that their economic posi- tion points distinctly to improved and more profitable farming. An unen- cimibered title to the land, the emancipation of labour from all local and communal burdens, the concentration of all force and all knowledge on the better employment of a holding granted "for eternity", the conscious- ness that trouble spent on the soil will not be lost — all this has had a mar- vellous influence on the whole course of farming as well as on the holders' daily Hves. Among individual peasants fixed and strengthening halnts of temperance are to be observed, habits which were introduced on that memorable day on which by the Tsar's will they were proclaimed as com- pulsory for the whole nation. URUGUAY. THE REFORM OF THE LAND TAX FROM THE POINT OF VIEW OF AGRICULTURE AND BREEDING. SOURCES : I^EY DE CONTRIBUCION INMOBILIAR PARA LOS DEPARTAMENTOS DEI, LITORAL E INTERIOR (LaW US to the Contribution of Real Estate in the Departments of the Coast and the Interior) Diario Oficia], No. 3018, 18 January 1916. ReCARGO en la CONTRIBUC16N INMOBILIARIA A LOS PKOPIETARIOS NO DOMICILIADOS EN EL Pais (Law Increasing the Contribution of Real Fstate far Proprietors not domiciled luithin the Countr}) Diario Oficial, N" 3029, 31 January 1916. Decreto reglamentario DE LA LEY QXJE ANiECEDE {Decree giving a ruling as to the Pre- ceding Law) Diario Oficial, No. 3029, 31 January 1916. BOLETIN DET MiNiSTERio DE iriACiENDA (Bulletin oj the Minister oj Finance) 2nd j^ear, Nos. 10, II and 12, 20 Oclober, 20 November and 20 DecemV)er 1915 ; 3rd year, Nos. i, 2 and 3, 20 Januan,', 20 February and 20 Match 191 6. A certain number of legislative measures bearing on finance have recently been promulgated by the government of the eastern republic of Uruguay. They are of interest, some of them directly and some indirectly, to rural landed propert)^ and agriculture ; and therefore they deserve detailed examination in this Review, the more so because they have given rise to long discussions in the general press and technical pubhcations and in Parliament. Moreover they tend, while they give a national basis to the land tax, to develop the value of rural landed property, for they devote a part of the new revenue arising from them to the making and the multi- plication of routes of communication in the interior of the country. They .should be regarded therefore not only as important modifica- tions of the national fiscal arrangements, biit also as an attempt to distrib- ute more equitably the tax which burdens landed property, while aim- ing at creating new revenues which will favour the appreciation of lands and proportionately increase the agriculturist's sources of profits. The measures which we will analy.se individualh^ are : (i) the law of 14 January 1916 as to the contribution to the revenue of real estate in the de^jartments of the coast and the interior ; (2) the law of the same date which increases the contribution of real estate and falls on landowners who are not domiciled within the countr^^; and (3) the decree of 27 JanuarA^ which regu- THE REFORM OF THE I,AND TAX I09 lates the public enforcement of the previous laws. The two latter meas- ures complete the regime instituted by the first. In view of the importance of the breeding of live stock, and of indus- tries thence derivative, to Uruguayan economy, we will devote a para- graph of this short study to the reaction of the new financial arrangements on tliis form of activity-, and will therefore briefly examine the present state of breeding in relation to fiscal burdens. § r. The xew t,aw as to the contribution of reai, estate. a) i*^ Chief Provisions. x\rticle I of the law of 14 January 1916 institutes an annual tax on privately owned real estate, whatever be the form of ownership, which is situated in any territory of the republic except the department of Monte- video. Tliis tax is one of 4 per thousand on the value of rural lands, apart from that of anj- improvements which they ma}^ have received, if their estimated value do not exceed 2500 pesos (i) and if the\' constitute the only rural property of their owner. On lands of which the estimated value exceeds 2500 pesos the tax is of 4 14 per thousand (2). Within urban and suburban districts it is of 6 y, per thousand, on the combined valued of land and improvements. According to article 3 owners of fields within rural districts, of which the area does not exceed 50 hectares (3) and of which at least 60 per cent. is under cultivation or has been reforested, will be taxed on only half the taxable value of these lands as determined by the valuation. When their total extent exceeds 50 hectares, only that portion of them which is destined for agriculture or forestation will benefit by this preference. Of the revenue yielded by the tax -of 6 ^4 P^r thousand on urban and suburban property i per thousand will accrue to the economic admi- nistrative commissions of each department and 5 14 P'^r thousand to the general revenue of the country. The product of the 4 I/2 P^r thousand tax on rural property will be divided as follows : (a) i per thousand to the economic administrative commissions of each department ; [h) ^ per thousand to the permanent fund for routes of comnumi cation : and [c) 3 per thousand to the general revenue of the State. Article 6 estabhshes that for the two financial years 1915-1916 and 1916-917 the tax on rural real estate will be fixed by the general directing body of land valuation and according to the estimated value determined b}' the new census of rural landed proi)erty, less 20 per cent. " The general direc- (i) I peso -= about 4.s- yi at par. (2) This preferential treatment ot small property was not provided In- the original scheme, which fixed the land tax at 5 per thousand without making distir.ction^. (3) I hectare = 2.47 acres. no URUGL'AV - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL tors of valuation ", runs the text of this article, " will take into account among other things, in fixing the value of rural property, the market price of the lands and the income they probably yield, the latter being taken to represent at least 4 per cent, of the estimated value". Article 23, which refers to appeals, recognizee a right in ever\' proprietor, who believes him- self to be wronged by the quota of the tax incident on his real estate, to demand a new valuation from the competent authorit}'. If he do not ac- cept this second valuation the dispute will be brought before a commission of experts who will comprise, as well as members of the local municipal administration and the administrations of finance and the cadaster, four landowners domiciled in the district and chosen by the executive authority from a list of the principal tax payers. The latter will be drawn up by the departmental financial authority. This commission will, in examining the values estimated by the census, take into account the selling price of neigh- bouring rural properties resembling those under consideration, making deductions for improvements, and also the rent of the real estate in question and of others in the district. Where such rent exists the value as estimated shall be considered as a capital bearing interest at a rate between 3 and 4 per cent. : that is to say that if a property, or adjacent lands of approxim- atety the same quaHty, be let at a rent of S 1.50 the hectare the estimated value cannot exceed S 50 nor be less than S 37-50. The parties concerned, that is to say the departmental agent of the administration of finance and the landowner, can appeal against these decsions of the local commission of experts to the central commission of experts constituted at IMontevideo and comprising the general director of direct taxation, the president of the rural association of Uruguay, and a rural landowner of the department whence the appeal arises who will be nominated by the executive power. The decision of the central commission will be final. Properties of which the value does not exceed 100 pesos are, among other real estate, exempted from pa3'ment of the tax, as are properties be- longing to rural societies and permanent^ assigned to agricultural exhibi- tions and competitions, and 50 per cent, of reforestation areas depending on agricultural and breeding establishments. We leave on one side all the provisions as to urban and suburban real estate, to examine which would be outside the scope of this article. The law will be in force, in the form \Ahich has been indicated, for two years. b) The Basis of the Law and the Census of Property. As can be seem from the brief summary \\liich we have giVen of the law's chief provisions, it is inspired by a principle which is already applied in other countries. The Uruguayan IMinister of Finances recalled, in the explanatory' note which he addressed on 26 November to the president of the financial commission of the Chamber of Representatives, for the better definition of THE REFORM OF THE LAND TAX the scheme then being studied, that he aimed at superseding the old method of taxing land according to rented value b^' that alread}- applied in Great Britain and Germany for the benefit of the State, and in Australia for the benefit of the municipalities, the method namely which was based on capi- tal or market values. The system hitherto in force in Uruguay' was that of taxation by dis- tricts. But the minister in this note observed that " the rudimentary and arbitrary regulation by districts could exist only while there were no other means of arriving at a trul}" equal distribution of the tax ; the method of taxing by districts interpreted in truth a principle in direct contradiction to the modern tendency of taxation, of which the incidence should be pro- portionate to the capacity to pa}^ " . To support his thesis the minister gave the following example. If in the same district there were fields worth respectively- S lOO, § 120, S 150, S 200 and 8 250 the hectare, their average value would be S 164, on which taxable value the 6 y2 P^r thousand tax would be imposed. But thus, in relation to the -true value of his property, each proprietor would pay at an inverse ratio to his capacity- to pay : the owners of the first field 10.66 per thousand, the owner of the second 8.80, the owner of the third 7.10, the owner of the fourth 5.33, and the owner of the fifth 4.30 To reach the present law a new census of rural propertA' was first necessar}^ until there rhould exist a sj'stematically drawn-tip cadaster, the preparation of which would take long. The new census has beecn completed with remarkable celerity in quite recent years. Those in charge of the valuation took into account, in determining the value of estates, data in the registry of sales, and in most cases they were able to obtain plans of the real estates and their dimensions from sur- veyors employed by private persons. Thus it was possible to prepare a sufficiently true and exact classification of rural properties. The necessary- basis therefore existed for applying to rural real estate the method of taxation already in force in the case of urban real estate, namely the method accordant with their precise and indi\ddual values; and the figures of the new census, which allow lands to be burdened accord- ing to the effective capital they represent, support the whole edifice of the reform we are considering. In adopting the capital value of landed property as the basis of the tax, the government of Uruguay took into account conditions which are peculiar to all new countries in the full period of their growth, when their natural resources are still far from being developed" or 3'ielding their maxi- mum return. The value of Uruguayan land may have fallen slightly in 1914-T915, owing to the extensive reaction from events in Europe ; but it remains a value of which the increase is certain in normal times, and which at present has in no way reached the highest point possible to it. The following table shows the progress in the value of the lands of the republic during the last ten years : 112 URUGUAY - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL Table I. — Increase in the Value of Landed Property. Value of Landed Year Property I9O4-I905 % 195,706,770 I905-I906 391,413,540 I906-I907 471,771,905 I9O7-I908 552,130,270 I90S-I9O9 632,488,635 I909-I9IO 712,847,000 1913-1914 1,069,270,500 I9I4-I915 855,416,400 It is evident that in face of such an increase in the value of property it would be foolish to fix the tax according to the returns received by a landowner who does not cultivate his fields himself, but who lets them in order that they may be made productive. c) The Product oi the Tax and its Application. The agrarian policy of the government of Uruguay' aims steadih' at the development of agriculture and breeding, the country's chief resources. We will not examine in detail the many measures which are proof of this constant preoccupation, but will merely note in passing that it devotes one million pesos a year to guaranteeing the railways which are of interest to rural districts, and has devoted about a million more to rural roads and bridges, and that it spends considerable sums annually on the sanitary inspection of animals, agricultural defence and such objects. In fact all forms of agricultural activity are encouraged and scientificalh' developed in the public interest of the country. This policy is from the strictly fiscal point of view the only logical one, as is clear when the receipts of the treasury from rural property and urban property, respectively, are considered. The purely conventional taxable value of rural propertj^ which was respected under the system of districts, was 8370,593,445 and this at 6 ^ per thousand 3-ielded §2,408,857, as against 8406,555 which was the effective value of urban and suburban propertj' and yielded a tax of $ 321,143. But the new census makes the difference much more considerable for it raises the taxable value (that is the amount of the capital value less 20 per cent.) of rural property to 3 712,000,000, which sum gives, when ijt is rendered liable to the 4 V^ per thousand tax, an annual yield of § 3,204,000, that is ten times the sum furnished by urban property which subsists unchanged. The importance to the government of a progressive increase in the capital formed b}' rural propert}' is thus seen, and the fact that y^ P^^ thousand out of the 4 ^2 P^r thousand tax will be paid into a special fund for roads and communications will not fail to contribute to this imoortance. The ne- THE REFORM OF THE LAND TAX II3 cessit^^ of making new and improving old roads cannot be questioned, for all the agricultural congresses untiringly insist on this point. For want of fixed resources for this end the public authorities have not hitherto been able to give the needed continuity to their roadmaking enterprise. The topographical conditions of Uruguay are very unfavourable to it, owing to the considerable number of watercourses which roads must cross and which must increase the costs of construction and maintenance. When a system of roads and paths has been established in all districts the transport of products will be facilitated and rendered infiniteh' less costly, and the value of the lands therefore increased. Under the system of districts the eighteen departments within the scope of the new law, which have an area of 17,064,865 hectares of rural land, disposed of only § 370,594 for bridges and roads, the employment of tliis sum being regulated by admin- istrative economic commissions. Under the new system the sum accru- ing to these commissions will be about -S 700,000, partly destined for the improvement of local roads. In addition about $ 350,000 a year will, as has been said, form the nucleus of a special permanent fvmd for bridges and roads, and this sum will increase proportionately with the increasing value of the lands. § 2. Breedin'g and the tax on reae estate. Before becoming law the scheme for reforming the land tax gave rise to the most lively discussion and was the object of many criticisms, especially on the part of stock breeders. These considered that the rate at which it was proposed that they should pay aggravated their burden, although breeding, the " mother industry " of the country, was already heavily taxed. The government did not not fail to examine the objections submitted by the stock breeders, who contribute very largely to the wealth of the country, and replied to them by giving precise data which allowed their partici- pation in public burdens to be exacth' estimated. On referring to the table giving the rise in the value of lands, it is seen that in ten years the capital represented by land has increased by 600,000,000 pesos. The 6 % per thousand contribution of real estate did not follow the growth in the value of real estate, and was still calculated on $423,000,000 instead of on .$ 1,069,270,500 in 1913, and on a little less than $900,000,000 in 1915. Thus the land tax represented a total annual burden of about is 2,730,000. The contribution of breeding to public and municipal revenue is re- presented by the export duty (i), as well as the land tax : namely bj' the port nient . i) The pri) luct^ ot the frceziny iiuhislry are (.xempted in onkr In tncnuragc its develop- 114 URUGUAY - AGRICULTURAL ECOXOMY IN GEXERAL dut}^ of I per cent., the charge of i 14 P^r thousand for the patent to circulate, the tax of 25 ten-thousandths a kilogramme on live stock intended for the freezing chambers, and the statistical tax. Altogether the fiscal burdens on breeding were equivalent in 1914-1915 to 4.62 per thousand of the value of riiral lands, as against 5.21 per thousand in 1911-1912 and 5.06 per thousand in 1909-1910. The following figures show the total amount of the fiscal revenue de- rived from breeding : Table II. — Fiscal Burdens on Stock-Breeding. Total Product of. the Various Year Taxes and — Duties I9O9-I9IO $ 3,606,677 I9IO-I9II 3,270,857 I9II-I9I2 . 4,459,685 1912-1913 4.3i9'533 1913-1914 3,920,622 1914-1915 %95S,^^7 Thus taxes on breeding do not furnish as much as four million pesos a year, in spite of the increase in value of landed property and the fact that the price of live stock has been multiplied by five in the last twenty years. The following table shows the variations in the price of live stock from 1 91 1 to 1915, according to the export figures. Table III.. Variations in the Price of Live Stock Exported in one Month, from 1911 to 1915. Kind of Live Stock September 191 1 W-. rt o a September 1912 I^IS September 1913 September 1914 September 1915 K-5 60° C Sua 60° .5 Bullocks Oxen . . Cows . . 6,951 1,177 5.968 26.61 10,105 29.59! 1,412 18.89J 7,208 Calves 2,9241 7. II; 1,370 26.34 ",933 33.85 1,014 23-30J 2,778 13-491 977 45-77 53-46 13,100 838 57-68 37,668 64.27 2,386,66.77 65.58 38.44! 7,344j45-84j 8,325146.72 21.64 1,85119.33 1,838120.45 As regards the development of the live stock industry, the data which we give below, and which refer to the export of the chief products of live THE REFORM OF THE LAND TAX II5 stock — salted and dried ox-skins, dried sheepskins, wool, frozen meat and preserved meat itasajo) — allow its stages to be followed. Table IV. — Annual Value of Exported Products of Live Stock. Official Values (approximate) 1892 $ 25,951,819 1905 $ 33,437.888 1893 27,681,373 1906 30,805,061 1894 33.479.511 1907 34,912,872 1895 32,543.644 1908 40,296,367 1896 30,403,084 1909 45,103,422 1897 29,319,573 1910 43,699,798 1898 30,276,916 1911 46,015,834 1899 36,574,164 ^^ ^ o^ (Effective values) 1900 29,410,862 I9OI 27,762,782 I912 53,041,855 1902 33.660,300 I913 69,771,530 1903 37.369.402 I9I4 51,208,955 1904 38,484,817 T915 (January- Aug.) 41,896,155 If we take into account only these values and not the circumstances, alleged by the breeders, that the considerable mortality among live stock last year has made their situation particularly difficult, we see that the value of the land has risen, that that of production has increased, that the frozen meat industry — which has a direct relation to breeding — has developed importantly, and that the total contribution of breeders to the State has diminished, absolutely and relatively. As the government has itself observed, it would profit by a suppres- sion of all secondary taxes and dues and the retention of only an " in- dustrial patent ", subsisting side by side with the land tax, as in the Argentine Republic where such patent amounts to 2 per thousand of the value of lands. For the moment the system in force has not however been changed in any way: products are taxed on leaving the country on the presumption that persons who have realized an industrial profit will thus contribute rather than the breeders. Since the law of 14 January 1916 was voted after a simple debate, the supposition is that the breeders have recognized its advantage, as shown by the arguments of the government supported b}' official statistics. § 3. The IvAnd tax and landowners not resident in the country. On 14 January 1916 the Parliament of Uruguay voted a law which completes that on the contribution of real estate. As therein provided, persons and corporations who are not domiciled in the country, that is whose business has its headquarters abroad, will pay double the tax im- Il6 URUGUAY - AGRICULTURAL ECOXOMY IX GENERAL posed by the law which we have examined. The same Habiht}^ attaches to landowners who, while they are domiciled in the territory' of the repub- lic, have been outside it for more than a year when the tax becomes pa3'able. Exemption from this additional liability is given to foreign com- mercial or industrial companies who are established in the country by a State grant, to the properties on which they conduct the industry or trade which is the object of the grant, and to certain properties in the coast watering-places of the country. The landowner affected by article I of this law, who does not make the stipulated payment, will be liable to a fine of 20 per cent, of the amount of the tax on his real estate, including the additional tax. Moreover by a clause which is proof of the desire to strike at the owner rather than the lessee, the law establishes that the additional tax is payable by the landlord, even if the lease stipulate that the land tax is to fall on the lessee. As a consequence of the provisions we have indicated, the decree regulating the law establishes that deposit and discount banks, credit banks and institutions, and societies and individuals who administer real estate belonging to the persons included by article i of the law, must in the course of February' of each year notify such fact to the directors of direct taxation in the capital and the administration of revenues in the departments, giv- ing all required information as to the name, qualit}' and domicile of the pro- prietors they represent. The administration will thus be able to prepare a register of absentee proprietors. The IVIinister of Finances has made a point of stating exactly, on ii March IQ16, the principle of the law, which is " to tax the absentee landlord, owing to the economic evil caused to a country by a j^roprietor letting his real estate to others who develop it with their own capital ". The government wished especially to exempt from this provision the large Liebig establishments, on the ground that the capital emploj'ed on this enterprise, which was at first foreign, has been so invested in Uruguay that there has been an incorporation of positive wealth, of a factor of pro- duction, and of an element which so raises the value of the products of breeding that it has given birth to a centre of industrial life, and caused a numerous labouring population to be established on the country's soil. MISCELIvANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL IN YARIOUvS COUNTRIES. ITALY. I. RECENT :MEASL'RES AS TO AGRICUI,TUR.\Iy CONTRACTS. — GazzeUa Uffidale del Regno d'ltalia, No. 261, Rome, 7 November igi6. B}' a decree of the Lieutenant General of the kingdom, dated 2 Nov- ember 1916, No. 1480, important steps have been taken as to agricultural contracts, always with the idea of helping agriculturists to overcome the difficulties of the present time. The principal provisions are as follows : Agricultural contracts in writing or by word of mouth, whether in- volving some system of partnership or a fixed wage, are not to have force until the year after that in which peace is made. The Arbitration Commis- sion of mandamento, of which there is question in Article 11 of the decree of 30 Ma}' 1916, No. 645 (i), can in every case grant, at the request of the cultivator, the wage-earner or the small farmer and on recognized and se- rious grounds, that the contract cease to bind at the end of the current agricultural year. The widow, children, parents or other heirs of the cultivator or small farmer who dies in the war, or as a consequence of the war, can, if they be part of his family employed in cultivating his holding, apply to the Arbitration Commission of mandamento for the delay of the contract as stated above, if they show proof that they are able to execute the clauses of such contract. In contracts involving the principle of partnership, where this impHes only a sharing of produce between the landowner and the cultivator, the former or his manager, or the cultivator or his representatives, may in the cases which have been mentioned bring onto the holding extra labourers, corresponding in number to those menAers of the cultivator's family who are with the colours or have been killed or disabled in the war, and the resultant expense shall be shared in the proportion fixed for the sharing of produce. In the case of small farmers' contracts drawn up before 24 May 1915, if the Arbitration Commission of mandamento recogniz^, at the instance of the lessee, that the insufficient cultivation of the leasehold, by reason (i) See Tniernatinuol Reiicu) of Aa.yicuUuyal Economics, October i')i6, iiagc. 119. IlS INFORMATION RELATIXC, TO AC~,RICULTURAL ECONOMY IX OENERAL of the call to the colours of members of the lessee's family, has placed it economicalh'' in a difficult condition, the commission may declare a reduc- tion of rent for the current year and for the succeeding years during which the delay continues, in a proportion not exceeding one half of such rent for each man called to the colours. In the case of contracts of any kind imposing fixed wages, the Arbi- tration Commission may exceptionally, if the parties have not come to an agreement, grant at the instance of the labourer, taking into account the conditions of labour and production, an increase of wages. The last part of the decree contains complementary provisions for the Arbitration Commissions of mandamento, and especially for the Provin- cial Commissions of Agriculture formed by Article 8 of the decree of 30 May 1916, No. 645. Persons representing economic institutions (agri- cultural co-operative societies), or technical institutions (agricultural com- mittees), or local institutions, are summoned to be members of these com- missions of which the task has been enlarged. They are charged : a) To make a levy of the labour available for agricultvire in the differ- ent zones of the province, using the authority of communes, and also that of the labour bureaux where these exist, and of the workmen's organ- izations and other social institutions publicly recognized or subsidized; and to estimate the adequacy or inadequacy of the supply of labour to the needs of local farms, organizing accordingly its displacement from one zone to another. h) To make a levy of the agricultural machines available in the pro- vince and facilitate the greatest possible use of them. c) To keep count of variations in the area devoted to each crop witliin the province, to notify the Ministry of Agriculture of the causes for changes, and make suggestions with a view to using uncultivated land to the greatest possible extent, d) To regulate and facilitate, by means of agreements with Commis- sions of Agriculture in adjacent provinces, migrations from one province to another, according to the supply of labour available and the needs of agriculture. The officials of communes, the inspectors of industry and labour, the holders of the peripatetic chairs of agriculture, and, generally, all officials depending on the Ministry of Agriculture, and all those nominated to legally recognized agricultural institutions and to social institutions sub- sidized by public authority, are bound to give their aid, when asked, to these Provincial Commissions. 2. RUIvES FOR GRANTINO THE TEMPORARY U.SR OF AGRICULTURAL, MACHINES. Among measures favouring agriculturists lately adopted by the Ital- ian government, one which deserves notice is that allowing the Minister INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL IIQ of Agrictilture {Decree of 6 June 1915, No. 826) to make large purchases of agricultural motors and machines of which agriculturists and rural or- ganizations will be allowed the temporary use. ^Machines thus bought mil be entrusted to the government depots which are managed as follows : In ever}- depot of agricultural machines and tools established by the Ministry of Agriculture there is, first, a manager who is helped by a secre- tary and responsible for the care of the machines and the dissemination of their use according to stated rules. By satisfying the demands of the agricultural schools, the committes, the associations, and the private agriculturists and macliine-makers, each depot meets the needs of rural economy in a fixed district assigned to it b}' the ministr3\ The manager himself keeps a register of all the machines, implements and tools in his depot, numbering and signing its pages himself. When- ever a machine or tool is received he enters its description in the register, sends to the ministry a receipt and certificate of acceptance, and notifies all the local agricultural schools, committees and communes, which are requested to notifj" the public. Whoever wishes to make trial of the machines and implements in the depot must apply in writing to the manager, stating which machine or tool he wants, the place in which it will be used and the time for which he in- tends to employ it. The manager may exact from any applicant that he give as surety for the price at which the machine is inventoried a person known to be solvent, or deposit a sum equal to such price. Thus it becomes possible to cover the loss of a lent machine, or the cost of necessary repairs, at the expense of the appHcant. The schools and agricultural committees are exempt from obligation to give a guaranteee. When a manager receives applications from agricultural schools, com- mittees or individuals outside the district assigned to his depot, he must send them to the ministry which reserves the right to consider and decide on them. Applications are granted in the following order : first those of the schools, then those of the committees and of associations existing in the general interest of agriculture, then those of members of the committees, and finally those of private agriculturists and of machine-makers who wish to study and copy the depot's machines in their workshops. Applications of the same kind are dealt with in order of priority'. When there are a number of applications for the same machine the manager must give the preference to whoever has not yet made trial of it. Without special leave from the ministry machines must not be granted for more than fifteen days or more than twice to the same individual. But they may be granted more frequently and for a longer time to agricultural committees and schools. The grantee is responsible from the moment at which he signs a re- ceipt for the machine. All costs of transport and maintenance and of ordinary- and other repairs are chargeable to him. 120 IXFORMATIOX RP:I.ATI.\G TO AGRICULTURAL ECOXOMV IX GEXERAL For every da}- for which the return of the machine is delayed beyond the term of the grant, the grantee must pay a fine as compensation and in- terest. Its amount will be previously determined b}' the manager of the depot according to the importance and value of the machine. When the machine is returned a report must be made, noting the con- dition in which it is brought back to the depot. Persons who have used the machines must, when returning them, pre- sent a detailed report on results obtained, costs incurred, and the conditions of weather and place in which trial of them has been made. In this report all results must be carefully compared with those which would have been obtained had ordinary expedients been used and customar}- local prac- tices followed. In making calcvilations allowance should be made for inter- est on the sum employed to purchase the machine or implement and for amortization. The manager must refuse to grant further machines to per- sons who have neglected to obey this provision which is of evident iitility. Finally, in the first month of every year the manager must present to the ministry a complete report of the trials of the machines and imple- ments in his depot during the preceding year. In forwarding this report he must suggest the replacement of machines which no longer meet local needs, either because they have undergone depreciation or because agri- tural mechanics have progressed. At the same time he must communi- cate an}' desires for new machines, of more recent or more perfect pattern, which have been expressed to him. 3. TILE FOUX'DATIOX OF AX " ISTITUTO AUTOX'OMO DI BOXIFICAMEXTO AGRA- RIO E DI COLONIZZAZTOXF; PERIvA SARDEGXA". — Gazzctta VfficialeddRes.no d'ltalia, Xo. 249, Rome, 23 October 1916. By a decree of the General Lieutenancy' of the kingdom, No. 1316, dated 3 September igi6, there has been founded at Sauluri (Cagliari) an autonomous in.stitute of agricultural beneficence and of colonization for Sardinia, and it has received for fifty j-ears the use of the experimental estate, formed on 25 November 1915, which comprises the large property called " Stabilimento Vittorio Emanuele ". This institute is obliged gradually to provide for works of agricultural benefit, land improvement and colonization, and for the division of its land into farms which will be granted to cultivators ; all according to plans approved by the Ministry of Agricultvire. For the purpose of these tasks the institute may receive preferential loans, and also advances and loans from institutions of land or agricultural credit and savings banks. It is further charged to promote the foundation of an agricultural bank and agricultural union, chiefly in the interest of the cultivators. It may also promote such co-operative consumers', labourers' and producers' associations as co-operative dairies, oilraills, cellars etc. INFORM ATIOX RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECOXOMY IX GEXERAL 121 The institute is ruled b}' an administrative council composed of two representatives of the Ministry of Agriculture, two of the Alinistry of Pub- he Works and one of the Ministry of Finances — all of whom are nomi- nated by royal decree — , and of a technical manager. The administrative council manages the property of the institute, nominates its emploj^ees, and sees that it pursues the objects which have been cited. The councillors hold office for three years and may be re- elected. They nominate a chairman from among themselves. The technical manager is respon.sible for the work of the institute, already defined : he prescribes and inspects systems of agriculture and agri- cultural works, and provides for the execution of the resolutions of the administrative council. The institute converts the returns from its property into its own in- come, which it uses to extinguish the loans it contracts and to pay the costs of administration and agriculture and of the maintenance of works of bene- ficence, as well as to meet every other necessarj' expense and to form a fund intended for later agricultural improvements. The Ministry of Agriculture acts, through an especial organization, as superintendent and guardian of the institute and of the agricultural enterprise accessory to it. 4. XATIOXAI, CHARITY FOR THE ORPHAXS OF PEASAXTS KILLED IX THE WAR* Constitution approved by a decree of the Geneial Lieutenancy ot the kingdom, 6 August IQ16, Xo. 1025. Gazzetta Ufficiale del Regno d'lialia, No. 201, Rome, 26 August 1916. We have already alluded (i) to the great movement which has for some time been spreading in Italy in favour of helping the orphans of peas- ants killed in the war, and also the active propaganda of the Istitido nq- zionale- delta mntuaUta agraria for the foundation of agricultural colonies especially designed for the reception of these orphans and their education in their fathers' callings. In order better to direct and co-ordinate this movement there has recently been formed in Rome the Opera nazionale per gli orfani dei contadini morti in guerra e per i figli del contadini resi in guerra pernianentemente inahili al lavoro. a national charity for the orphans of peas- ants killed in the war and for the children of peasants permanently dis- abled b}' the war, which acquired .status as a corporation having a moral aim by a decree dated 6 August 1916, No. 1025. Its objects are : a) to see that aid is given to the orphans of peasants by special lo- cal protective agencies (2) or other institutions; (i) See International Review of Ai^riculUiral Economics, March 191 6. (2) See in this connection an interesting pamphlet by Dr. Mario Casalini, geinial sccretarj- of the charity, " L'Assistenza agli orfani dei contadini. I patronati, hi loro orszanizzazione il loro funzionamcnto ". Chiusi, typ. Cerere, 1916. 122 INFORMATION RKLATING TO AGRICULTURAL KCONOMY IN (iKNERAL b) to promote and favour the formation of protective agencies and agricultural colonies in the various districts of Italy, with a view to receiv- ing such of these orphans and children of peasants as cannot obtain either help or a fit technical education within their families ; c) to co-ordinate the activity of local protective agencies, agricultural agencies, and other institutions having analogous aims ; d) to promote one or more institutions capable of being connected with the existing institutions of agricultural credit, in order to help the or- phans to buy small rural holdings which they will themselves farm when they have reached majority. Wherever there are already protective agencies or agricultural colo- nies, legally constituted and recognized by the charity, the duty of helping the peasants' children generally falls on them. Where there are none the charity renders e.special aid to these orphans by means of delegates. When it has accomplished its duty to the orphans of peasants killed in the war it will extend its benefits to other peasants' orphans. To com- pass its aims it disposes of a) the eventual income of its property : b) the annual subscriptions of ordinary members and subscribing societies ; c) the subscriptions of honorary members ; d) the donations, legacies, tempor- ary donations and extraordinary income which will eventually accrue to it. Its members belong to the following categories : a) members giving a donation, in other words all co-operative and mutual aid institutions which contribute more than 50 liras a year ; b) ordinary mem^bers, those sub- scribing 10 liras a year ; c) benefactory societies, namely every institution, ministry, province, commune, savings bank, chamber of commerce, or- ganization or individual giving an annual subsidy of at least 100 liras ; d) perpetual honorary members, namely institutions which make one con- tribution of at least 100 liras. The capital paid by the honorary members is inaHenable, and only its income can be used to constitute or complete maintenance bursaries for the orphans. There are ordinary and extraordinary general assemblies of members. The former meets once a year to discuss and approve the report of the charity's moral and techrucal activity and to choose the general council. Its resolutions are fully valid if at least a tenth of the regularly inscribed members be present at it, or one hour after the time indicated in the invitation to the meeting for its opening, whatever number of members be present. When there is question of modifying the by-laws one fifth of the members are needed to constitute a quorum. Resolutions are passed by an absolute majority. This charity is managed by a general council of twenty-nine members who elect from among themselves a president, three \'ice-presidents, and an executive committee consisting of the president, the vice-president of oldest standing, five ordinary members of the council and a secretary. The members of the council and the executive committee hold office for three years. The council meets regularly twice a year. It administers the charity's INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 1 23 property, and approves reports for the general meeting and balance-sheets drawn up by the executive committee. The latter administers the charity udthin the Umits of its budget, and prepares and submits to the general council budgets and balance-sheets, the report on the moral and technical acti\'ity of the charity, etc : If the general meeting should decide to dissolve the charit}' its pro- perty will pass to the National Bank of Thrift. Propaganda in favour of the formation of the agricultural colonies and protective agencies, already mentioned, has met with excellent re- sults: there are already several agricultural colonies; and numeirous pro- tective agencies for the assistance of peasants' orphans have been consti- tuted, especially b}' the initiative of provinces, each of which will have its own agency. There is in Ital}^ a typical example of institutions of this kind, the Opera per I'assistenza e la educazione professionale degli orjani dei lavoraton della terfa, a charity for aiding and technically educating the orphans of agricultural labourers in the province of Bologna. * * * 5. AN IMPORTANT SCHEME FOR THE FOUNDATION OF A PROVINCIAL INSTITU- TION OF SOCIAL AID. Communicated by the provincial deputation of Bergamo on 7 April 191 6. At a recent meeting of the provincial council of Bergamo the found- ation was proposed of a large institution of social aid which should be formed on the initiative of the provincial deputation, and with the co-oper- ation of aU public and private institutions " interested in and responsible for the protection of public health and the economic and social welfare of the working classes ". The proposed institution would act through two sections — a hygienic and sanitary and a social and economic section. It would be the task of the latter : I. Statistics : a) To collect, collate and publish information as to la- bour — chiefly in regard to its organization and renumeration in Italy and in foreign countries, preferably those to which there was emigration ; and as to the relations of labour and capital ; the number and conditions of labourers and the conditions of unemployment ; strikes and their causes and results; and the number, causes and consequences of accidents to workmen ; b) To discover the development of the retrogression and the technical and economic conditions of social institutions in the province, as well as their influence on the welfare of the working classes and on the progress of agriculture. II. Legislation : c) To disseminate among the people a knowledge of social legislation, and to undertake all the studies and researches in matters of legislation which the government, the higher council of labour or other institutions should require. 124 IXFORMATIOX RELATING TO AGRICUWURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL III. Inspectorate : d) To see that all social and labour legislation was applied, and denounce those contravening it to the competent authorities. IV. Conciliation : e) To settle amicably disputes between employers and workmen and between the latter and contractors, and in general aU disputes as to agreements relative to labour contracts. V. Placing of labour : f) To place workmen and wage-earners, receiv- ing offers of and demands for work, bringing workmen and emplo^'ers together, and facilitating the conclusion of contracts. VI. Thrijt, mutual aid, co-operation: g) To contribute generahy to a large development of saving, thrift, mutual aid and co-operation in the working classes, and to render the organization of mutual and co-opera- tive societies more eflScient by co-ordinating them in federal institutions ; and especially ; h) To indiice working people, by means of an active propa- ganda and increased assistance, to join individually or collectively the Cassa nazionale di previdenza per I'invalidita e la vecchiaia degli operai, a national thrift bank providing against the disablement and old age of work- ing people, and other government institutions of thrift (Cassa nazionale di assicurazione per gl'infortuni degli operai sul lavoro, National Fund for Insiurance against the Accidents of lyabour) ; i) To popularize rules for the constitution and the successful working of co-operative associations of cre- dit, labour, production, consumption etc. ; thrift and mutual societies in their different forms ; societies for mutual insurance against mortality among live stock, damage done by fire or hail and the accidents of labour ; mutual aid societies ; mutual educational and forestry societies, etc. ; as well as aU institiitions aiming at the moral and material improvement of the masses ; and to help the establishment of such societies on the most scientific and practical models; ?') To help and to superintend all the economic institutions by means of frequent inspections, inducing them to keep regular accounts, and directing co-operative and mutual organization towards a uniform system of book-keeping which would produce scientific and uniform records fitted to be the material of statistical labour. This section proposes to reach its aim : a) B}- propaganda, oral and written ; assistance given to the social and economic institutions in the mat- ter of technique and book-keeping ; legal advice and aid in the matter of giving opinions, solving problems, arranging reconciliations, etc. {peripa- tetic chair of thrift and mutuality) ; b) By competitions, exhibitions or other forms of encouragement to the better economic institutions, and by propa- ganda and social aid. There would be assigned to the maintenance of the institution : a) an annual sum allotted by the province and provided by a special fund; b) the annual contributions or subsiches of public or private institutions (ministries, national bank of thrift, savings bank, communes, agricultural societies, etc.) ; c) the donations and legacies which might accrue; d) various income. To take charge of the administration and working of the institution there would be a council of eleven members — six of them chosen by the provincial council and five by a meeting of the representatives of the soci- INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL I25 eties which had contributed to the institute —, an executive committee, and a committee of official arbitrators having three effective members and two \'ice-members. UNITED STATES. OVERTIME IN THE FRUIT AND VEGETABLE CANNING AND PACKING INDUSTRY OF OREGON. — Monthly Review of the U, S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Washington , July 191 5. The Oregon Industrial Welfare Commission published under date of 26 May 1914 an order providing for the issiie of emergenc}^ overtime per- mits to fruit and vegetable canning and packing establishments. Such overtime is not to be permitted for more than six calendar weeks, and the whole working time, including overtime, is not to exceed sixty hours in any calendar week nor ten hours in any day. The following is the order in full. " Take Notice : That pursuant to the authority granted by chapter 35, General Laws of Oregon, 1915, the industrial welfare commission has investigated the emergency overtime requirements of the fruit and vege- table canning and packing industry of Oregon and finds that for six (6) weeks of each 3^ ear the aforesaid industry requires emergency overtime be- yond the fift3^-four (54) hours a week prescribed as maximum hours for wo- men workers in such industry in I. W. C. Orders No. 2 and No. 5. " Wherefore, the industrial welfare commission authorizes and per- mits the employment of adult women in fruit and vegetable canning and packing establishments in the State of Oregon for more than fifty-four (54) hours a week under the following conditions and rules which the afore- said commission hereby today determines and prescribes : " (i) Such emergency overtime shall not be permitted for more than six (0) calendar weeks, from May i to December i in any year. " (2) The emergency overtime shall not exceed the fifty-four (54) hours a week now prescribed by I. W. C. Orders No. 2 and No. 5 by more than six (6) hours for any calendar week. " (3) Nothing in this permit or order shall be interpreted as authoriz- ing the employment of any woman for more than ten (10) hours in any day. " (4) Such emergency overtime shall be paid for at a rate of not less than twenty-five cents (25c) an hour ; and the earnings for emergency over- time shall in no case be included in the weekly minimum wage prescribed by the rulings of the commission, but shall in every case be over and above the weekly minimum wage prescribed by I. W. C. Orders No. 2 and No. 5 for adult women workers. " (5) The owner or manager of every fruit and vegetable cannery or packing establishment in Oregon employing women under this emer- gency overtime permit shall furnish the industrial welfare commission on 126 IXFOJIMATTON RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL or before the 5th day of each month a transcript, duly verified as hereinaf- ter provided, of the weekly time and pay roll of each woman who has work- ed more than fifty-four (54) hours in any one week of the pfeceding month. Said transcript shall furnish the name and employee number of each wo- man employee. (6) Said transcript shall be verified by said owner or manager or some person in his behalf having knowledge of the facts by subscriVjing and swearing to a statement that said transcript is a full, true and accurate statement of the ov-ertime worked by and the wages paid to each and every woman who has worked overtime ". RUGGER! ALFREDO, gerente responsabilc (c] Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases. I. inLLS in Dalmatia Page 11 General Remarks, page 11. — § i. Capital of Installation, page 12. — § 2. Grants and Facilities for Credit, page 13. — § 3. The Oilmills, page 14. — § 4. General Results, page 15. Canada. Recent Successes of Agricultural Co-operation in Canada Page § I. Introduction, page 18. — §2. The Saskatchewan Co-operative Elevator Com- pany, page 19. — § 3. The Alberta Farmers' Co-operative Elevator Company, page 20. — § 4. The Manitoba Grain Growers' Grain Company, page 22. — § 5. The Fusion of Two Great Farmers' Companies, page 23. MisceI/IvAneous Information REiyATmc to Co-operation and Asso- ciation IN Various Countries Page British India : The Progress of Co-operative Societies in Baroda State, page 25. Italy : i) The Resolutions of the National Meeting of the Agricultural Co-operative So- cieties at Milan, page 26. 2) The Collective Farm of San Giovanni in Croce, page 27. IV CONTENTS 3) The " Societa Anoiiima Cooperativa per I'Esportazione dei Piodotti Agri- coli " of Jesi in 1915-1916, page 28. 4) The Activitj' of the Office of I^egal Advice of the " I,ega Nazionale delle Coo- perative ", page 29. 5) The Formation of the " Societa degU Enotecnici Italiani ", page 30. 6) The Development of the " Uuione Cooperativa di Milano ", page 30. Russia : The Finnish Superintending Societies in the years 1913-191 j, page 32. PART II : INSURANCE AND THRIFT. Uruguay. The State Bank of Insurance and Insurance against Hail. Page 35 § I. The State Insurance Bank, page 35. — § 2. Terms of a Policy of Insurance against Hail, page 36. — § 3. The Activity of the Department for Insurance against Hail, page 39. ]VIiscEi,i.ANEous Information rei^ating to Insurance and Thrift IN Various Countries Page' 43 Algeri.a. and Regency of Tunis : The Central Algerian and Tunisian Frmd for Agri- cultural Reinsurance in 1915, page 43. France : The Mutual Agricultural Fire Insurance Society of the East on i January 1916, page 44. Italy : i) The Proposals of Senator Conti's I,aw for compelling the Insurance of I^an^ against the Accidents of Peasants' I^abour, page 46. 2) The Mutual Insurance of Live Stock intended for Butcherj-, page 48. 3) The Rules for the District Offices of Agricultural MutuaJitj-, page 50. 4) A New Mutual Insurance Society against the Accident-^ of Agriculture, page 51. 5) Italian Savings on 30 June 1916, page 51. Russia: Finnish Societies for Insurance against Mortality among I^ive Stock in 1913, page 54- PART III : CREDIT. Algeria. Credit for CoLONiz.'i.TioN in Algerl\ Page 57 § I. The Character of the Credit afforded to Colonization, page 58. — §2. The Sources of the Capital assigned to Agricultural Credit, page 59. — § 3. The Role of the Banque de I'Algerie, page 60. CONTENTS Canada. Scheme for the bRG.\NizATioN of Rural Mortgage Credit inM.\nitoba, Saskatche- wan AND Alberta Page 63 MiscEivi^ANEous Information reivATing to Agricui^turai, Economy m GENERAL IN Various Countries Page 68 .Argentine Republic: The Franco-Argentine Mortgage Bank in 1915-1916, 1 age 68. French Colonies : The Discount and lyoan Transactions of Colonial Banks, page 70. RussL^ : The Question of Forest Credit in Finland, page 73. PART IV : AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL. Austria and Hungary. Agrarian Taxes in Bosnia .and Herzegovina Page 75 § I. Agrarian Taxes in the Period of Turkish Dominion, page 75. — § 2. Agrarian Taxes after the Occupation by Austria and Hungary, page 80. Great Britain and Irei,and. Agriculture and the War Page 87 ITAI^IAN SOMAIyll^AND. lyAND Tenure and Colonization Page 94 § I. General Remarks. Administrative Organization of Italian Somaliland, page 95. — § 2. Agricultural Conditions in Somaliland, page 98. — § 3. The I^and System, page loi. — § 4. Experiment and Experience in Colonization, page 105. — § 5. Schemes for Colonization in Somaliland by Italian FamiUes, page 108. MlSCEI,I.ANEOUS InFOR1\L\TION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAX ECONOMY IN General in Various Countries Page 116 Belgium : Agricultural Training for Partially Disabled Soldiers, page 116. France: The Department for Civil and Military Vegetable Gardens, page 118. New Zealand: Settlement of Discharged Soldiers on the Land, page 120. RussLA : i) The Forests of Finnish Towns, page 121 . 2) The Position and the Activity of the Grain Elevators of the Government and the Railway Companies, page 124. Part 1 : Co-operation and Association GERMANY. THE GENERAL RAIFFEISEN FEDERATION IN 1914-1915 {concluded) (i). § 2. The Rurai, Banks {Spar- imd Darlehnskassenvereine) The rural banks constitute 80 per cent of all the 5,680 co-operative societies belonging to the General Raiffeisen Federation, for they number 4,598. At the end of 1914 there were 4,558 rural banks. In 1915 fortj^- eight more joined the federation while eight left it. The increase was therefore one of forty societies. In 1914 it had been one of seventy-three. All the rural banks are unlimited liability societies. The report on these societies for 1914 was presented by 4,421 rural banks — 137 of them not reporting because their whole staffs had been mobilized. The 4,421 societies included 485,416 members, that is an average of no for one society. The increase since 1913 was one of 8,839 members, the membership of 1913 having increased by 15,206 on that of 1912, which year had recorded an increase of 17,069 on 191 1. The capital in shares of the 4,421 rural banks was 5,057,345 marks (2), the reserve fund 32,778,993 marks, the working capital 827,605,640 marks. The turnover was less in 1914 than in previous years, namely : 1914 — 1.435. 215. 859 marks ; 1913 — 1,572,013,669 marks ; 1912 — 1,573.887.576 marks. The decrease is a result of the restriction of credit during the war. (i) See first part in our issue for February 191 7, page i. (2) I mark = about 11 Vi d. at par. GERIVIANY - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATIOX Savings. Savings amounted to 82 per cent, of the year's capital, namely 682,618,933 marks, and had increased by 33,956,963 marks on those of 1913- The increase did not however arise out of increased paj'ments but out of a diminution of deductions, as appears from the following figures : Pasinents Deductions I9I2 204,175,046 168,881,862 I9I3 214,520,120 173,843,266 I9I4 195.843-529 152,286,744 Savings paid in were less in 1914 than in 1913 and 1912. But since here also the amount of deductions was less an increase in the total amount of savings resulted. The rate of interest paid b}' the banks to savers was from 3 to 6 per cent., having been from 3 to 5 per cent, in 1913. Current Accounts at the Central Bank. At the end of 1914 the rural banks had debited current accounts at the Central Bank amounting to 68,772,537 marks. The debt was less by 9,819,567 marks than its amount in 1913 and less by 8,430,541 marks than its amount in 1912. As a consequence of this decrease in current account liabilities and the increase in current account credit the rural banks, which were the debtors of the Central Bank before the war, had become its creditors, for their cre- dit accounts with this bank reached the sum of 95,139,579 marks as against 78,302,126 marks in 1913. Credit for Fixed Terms. Such credit amounted to 61.5 per cent, of the whole assets of the rural banks, namely 499,673,745 marks out of 832,006,308 marks. The increase since 191 3 was of about eight million marks but it re- sulted, as the following figures will show, not on increased new credit but on diminished repa3^ments : Credit granted Repayments I9I3 98,763,252 70.776,473 I9I4 72,001,670 57,306,084 The rate of interest paid by members to the rural banks was from 3 ^/4 to 8 3^ per cent., as compared to its rate of from 3 to 7 per cent, in 1913. THE GENERAI, RAIFFEISEN FEDERATION Current Accounts with Members. The currents account of the societies' banks and their members increase from year to A-ear. In 1914, 3,536 rural banks — 80 per cent, of them — had opened current accounts with their members. The total amounts of these current accounts were as follows : Credit current accounts 45>i52 for 123,722,498 marks Debit » » 24,606 32,567,379 " A new circumstance appeared in connection with these accounts. Previously the sums paid by members into the banks were alwa^'s less than those paid bj- banks to members, but in 1914 the converse was true, as appears from the following figures : Payments by Members Payments by Banks I9I2 132,879,067 144,539,139 I9I3 136,225,301 149,073,587 I9I4 131,203,766 127,860,370 If the totals of incoming and outgoing sums be examined the follow- ing conclusions are reached : 1. The total receipts — payments of members in savings and to cur- rent accounts, repayments of debts by members, credit granted by the Cen- tral Bank — , and the total disbursements — credit granted to members, repayments of sums due to members and to the Central Bank — were less than in previous years. 2. The total receipts exceeded the total disbursements. This is the contrary of what was true of earlier years and is explained by the restrict- ed credit granted during the war ; Total Receipts Total Disbursements 1912 407,214,867 marks 423,903,591 marks 1913 421,521,894 » 421,680,105 » 1914 384.353.379 » 352,148.784 » In addition to credit transactions many rural banks buy and sell merchandise on behalf of their members. The purchase of merchandise was practised by 3,917 rural banks. The value of the bought merchandise was 54,326,650 marks as against 68,641,827 marks in 1914. GERMANY - CO-OPERATIOX AND ASSOCIATION The details of purchases show that the following sums were spent on the following articles in the two years compared : Manure. Forage. Combustibles Seeds. . . ^Machines. Various. 21,892,942 marks 17,476,904 )' 6,456,275 » 2,189,015 » 910,322 » 6,049,771 » 23.979-835 marks 19,899,825 6,973,625 » 2,532,716 " 1.344.194 '■ 4,451,265 » The sale of merchandise for members was unimportant, special co-oper- ative societies having been created for this object. The value of the mer- chandise sold by the rural banks was 2,743,861 marks. For the 4,421 rural banks the year's books were closed showing : a profit in the case of 3,884 which realized altogether 3,212,113 marks of profit; a loss in that of 516 >) lost » 523,214 » . Twenty-one realized neither a loss nor a profit. The net profits were therefore 2,688,899 marks, as against 2,852,416 marks in the previous year. Co-operative Societies of CoxsuiiPTiox, Production axd Labour. At the end of 1914, 1045 co-operative societies of this kind belonged to the General Raiffeisen Federation. In 1915 it was joined by thirty- six more while fifteen ceased to belong, so that the total membership was 1066, distributed as follows : THE GENERAL RAIFFEISEX FEDERATIOX I. Co-operative Consumers' Societies II. Co-operative Producers' Societies 1. Dairies 310 2. Cellars 44 3. Distilleries 52 4. Essication of Potatoes ... 16 5. Granaries 20 6. Sale of Live Stock .... 26 7. Various 20 in. Co-operative Labour Societies. 1. Threshing 82 2. Employment of Electric Pow- er 316 3. Various in IV. Co-operative Breeding and Pas- turage Societies V. Co-operative Societies of Arti- sans and Tradesmen . . . VI. Various 31 December 1914 31 December 1915 51 65 48S 489 309 43 52 17 20 28 20 4^7 20 9 60 83 315 16 414 22 9 67 These societies had the foUowins: forms Unlimited liabiHty societies. Limited » » 262 760 258 782 It is seen that those of the second kind had become more numerous, those of the first fewer. In the case of all the kinds of co-operative socie- ties which have been enumerated the prevalent t3*pe is that of a limited liability society, except in the case of collective cellars which are held b}- unlimited liabilit}- societies in forty out of forty-three cases. Of all the co-operative societies existing at the end of 1914 only 807 reported on their business. Owing to the mobilization of their staffs 215 made no report. Co-operative Societies for the Purchase and Sale of Merchandise. At the end of 1914 there were fifty-one consumers' co-operative socie- ties and twenty co-operative granaries. During 1915 there were fourteen new adhesions, so that at the end of the 3'ear there were eighty-five socie- ties, sevent^'-five having limitec^and ten unlimited liability. Of this num- ber only forty-eight reported on their business in 1914. GERIVIAXY - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The total number of their members was 4,109. Their capital in shares was 901,755 marks, their reserve fund 929,929 mark, and their ^^ear's capital 12,358,026 marks. It is worth mentioning that the capital of the un- limited liability co-operative societies is a little higher than that of those having limited liabilit3^ Purchases were less important than in previous 3-ears owing to the small quantities of goods on the markets. The societies bought the follow- ing amounts on behalf of their members : manure 373. 706 zentners (i) forage 351,278 » seeds 10,338 » The total value of the goods thus bought was 5,955,745 marks as against 9,364,538 marks in 1913. The value of the merchandise sold on behalf of members was 922,296 marks 44 societies closed their year's books showing a total profit of 479,997 » 2 « a ;> i> » » » » loss » 1,931 » 2 ' ') » » » » no profit or loss. The total net profits thus amounted to 478,066 » 2. Dairies. There were 310 of these at the end of 1914. In 1915 one other joined and two retired from membership, and therefore at the end of 1915 there were 309 — 149 having unlimited and 160 having limited liability. Only 286 reported on their business, 277 of these owning their own premises while eleven held them on lease. The number of their members was 25,038. Their capital in shares was 1,204,928 marks, their reserve fund 2,478,715 marks and their year's capital 14,760,648 marks. If the large capital employed in these enterprises (8,748,583 marks) be considered it is seen that they ought to seek for more capital of their own. The data as to the delivery of milk have been furnished by only 231 societies, and show a yield of 258,439,247 litres (2) of milk ; and 633,711 kilogrammes (3) of cream, representing 4,119,122 litres of milk — that is a total of 262,558,369 litres of milk. (i) I zentner = no lbs. (2) I litre = 0.88 quart. (3) I kilogramme = 2.2 lbs. THE GENERAL RAIFFEISEN FEDERATION For the milk and cream delivered 26,373,553 marks, or an average of 0.102 mark a litre, has been paid to members. The milk was used as follows : sold as delivered 25,333,368 litres or 9.8 per cent used to produce cream. . . 7,000,000 » » 2.8 » » » » » cheese. . . 11,251,106 » » 4.4 « » » » » butter. . . 217,973,895 )' » 84 » » 277 dairies (i) closed their books showing a total profit of 805,958 marks 51 » {2) » » » » » » loss » 243,245 » 8 » « )) » » no profit or loss. The net profits therefore amounted altogether to 562,713 marks 1914 was a less profitable year than 1913. 3. The Collective Cellars. These numbered fortj^-four at the end of 1914. In 1915 two retired from membership and there was one new adhesion. At the end of the year the total number was therefore forty-three, forty having unlimited and three limited liabilit3^ The greater number of unlimited liabilitj' socie- ties in this group is due to the fact that almost all of them were formed in a period in which the Raiffeisen principles were strictly observed. Forty- one reported on their activity but without much detail. ^ The number of members was 2,233. 'The capital in shares was 141,853 marks (3), the reserve ftmd was 175,398 marks and the year's capital 2,731,389 marks. There are no data as to the quantity of grapes delivered to the so- cieties. 21 co-operative cellars closed their year's books showing a total profit of . . . 32,392 marks 17 » » " >> » » » » » loss :> . . . 128,082 i> 3 ' 11. » » " » ' neither profit nor loss. - /[.The Distilleries. There were 52 of these at the end of 1914 and throughout 1915. All or nearly all the distilleries are in East Prussia where the potatoes which are distilled are grown. Thirty-six of them belonged to the district feder- ation of Dantzig, nine to that of Koenigsberg and four to that of Breslau. Thirty-one of them have limited and sixteen unlimited liability, while (i) in 1913 : 335 dairies made a profit of 1,033,098 marks (2) » 1913 : 37 » . . loss » i59>530 that is 372 » » " net profit 873,568 » (3) The societies' own capital was insufficient if the fixed capital necessary to the enter- prise be considered. ^ GERMANY - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION five are not subject to any rule of the law on co-operative societies. Only thirty- four reported on their work. The total number of their members was 617. Their capital in shares was 413,702 marks, their reserve fund 155,789 marks, their 3'ear's capi- tal 2,240,730 marks and their fixed capital 1,596,860 marks. The capital belonging in their own right to the unlimited liabihty societies was equal to 6.8 per cent, of their year's income. In the case of the limited liability societies, this percentage was 23.7. Only twenty-four distilleries have furnished data as to their produc- tion. These had used 324,519 zentners of potatoes, 1,798 zentners of beet- root, and 1,678 zentners of Jerusalem artichokes. Of this quantity' mem- bers had delivered only 290,423 zentners ; the rest had been bought in the market. The co-operative societies had paid 1.79 marks for the potatoes which had been delivered. Owing to statutory restrictions production had been less than in the previous year. 5. Essication of Potatoes. Only sixteen co-operative societies of this kind belong to the General Raift'eisen Federation, two of them have unlimited and twelve of them limited liability while two are not subject to the law on co-operative societies. All these sixteen societies reported on their activity, as did five otjjer societies which essicate potatoes as an accessory business. They comprised 936 members, they had a capital in shares of 341,509 marks, a reserve fund of 96,935 marks, a year's capital of 2,255,748 marks and a fixed cap- ital of 1,278,360. The sixteen societies treated 1,216,071 zentners of potates by essica- tion, the other five 138,173 zentners. Of these quantities 938,512 zent- ners were delivered by members and 109,119 zenters by other producers, while 168,440 zentners were bought in the market. The resultant produc- tion was of 339,370 zentners of potato flakes and 32,665 zentners of potato slices. The greater share of these products was remitted to the members and others from whom the raw material had been bought, only 165,161 zentner- of flakes and 5,500 zentners of slices being sold in the market. 6. The Sale of Live Stock. Co-operative societies having this object have only existed for a few years and are all in East Prussia where the production of live stock is great- ly in excess of the consumption. There were twenty-six of them at the end of 1914, and in 1915 there were three new adhesions while one society retired from membership. At the end of 1915 there were therefore twentj'-eight societies, namely eleven in the Koenigsberg district federation, eight in that of Dantzig, seven in that of Berlin, and two each in those of Coblentz and Ludwigshafen. THE GENERAL RAIFFEISEN FEDERATION All are limited liabilit}^ societies. The}^ regularly sell live stock on commission. Only two of them buy their members' live stock and resell it in the market on their own account. Only fourteen reported on their business and they did not give detail- . ed data. The number of members was 5,835, the capital in shares 17,750 marks, the reserve fund log, 320 marks, the year's capital 329,950 marks. 7. Co-operative Threshing Societies. There were eightj-two of these at the end of 1914,. and at the end of 1915 eighty-three of which fifty-nine had limited and twenty-five unlimi- ted liability. The data as to their business were furnished by seventj^-four societies of whom twelve gave few details. Their members numbered 1,907, their capital in shares was 10^,072 marks, their reserve fund 37,539 marks, the year's capital 646,965 marks, of which the greater part was represented by the value of the machines. The yeai's capital varies notably according to whether a society owns or hires its machines. .30 societies closed tlieir books showing a total profit of 11,639 marks 32 » •) » » » » » loss >' 25,579 )) 12 » » >' » » neither profit nor loss. The losses result on an insufficient use of the machines. They wo^^" ed in 1914 for 36,101 hours, that is on an average 582 hotirs for each so- ciety, instead of 37,835 hours of work and an average of 641 for one so- ciety' as in 1913. 8. Co-operative Societies for the Employment of Electric Power. The first co-operative society of this kind was formed in 1906. At the end of 1914 there were 316 of them, and at the end of 1915 there were 315 of which nine had unlimited and 307 limited liability. Only a few societies own their plant : most of them hire their electric power on lease from an enterprise and distribute it among their members. 213 of them reported on their work in 1914. Their members numbered 15,396, their capital in shares was 159,490 marks, their reserve fund 8,364,052 marks, their fixed capital 4,991,445 marks. Ill societies closed their books showing a total profit of 44,365 marks 97 ,; » ., 1) » » » loss )) ....... 31)584 ' 5 ,, » a » )) neither profit nor loss. The following table gives data as to co-operative societies less import- ant than those with which we have dealt : 10 GERM.\NY - CO-OPERATIOX AND ASSOCIATION OOOOu-j vOfOCT^fOw pT i-T cfl m" pT i-T 'i- O M M o N CTv fO M N HI w M Tt- 0^ ON O lO ro t-~ lO ro o" O *<:f M M CO t^ t^ M ro On in On M t>. o T^ ^ M_ lO oo'o ON On CO N oo O^ ^ rooo t^ lO O 1^ woo r^ M M 00 t>- lO in 1>1 o" Tt- M 00 O^GCONMHCOHt^O ONoo M ovo inioinvD w c^ N q- oo_ Tf- Tt- -^ vo^ (o^ o__ pT t-^ d lo lo n" onoo" t^ O WHO t^ t>-00 lO O-/ H H 01 N -^ Tf 00 PI t^o o t>t- 00 O N 01 O N ro u-> C^ M t^ O vO OO ^ ro t^ C^ On fO H O* O O Tl-CO On CO On M H in H N ^ in ro^ o vo P< in in 00 to t^ o -^ o w CO O P) N vO t^ p) On o po M m t-^ md" pT o" •a E i>->n>no o '*--*-o ■^int^o pivo mo in PI On PO On C< 00 O P< O M 1~^ i-i cfv in o t^ On O PI 00 po o in r^ PI M HI t^ -^o ro H ro !>. N o -^ On m PI p( N in M H fO in po N CO r^o M- PO t^iO 00 PI in 00 fo PO in PO PO M W PI m t^ 00 PO N PO P4 ^ w l^ ON CO O t^ o t^ M M Hi f^ N vD On '5- CO o P4 in PI M C^ in M O ^ e T3 -a yj « -3 -^ ■ti V s ft H nlim imit ^ s CO p» PI M 1 1 ■^MMplMVOO On O"*--^ 4; .2 u V > rt 2 fl 00 00 X t; iJ >, U) OJ BO 1^ 3 fc ii (!-• ^ a> 'O ^ CU 'O « 3 O ;-! .3 (50-- .9 .i; o g E-25 a «J 2 a-a o MSi •§,1 2 §2 AUSTRIA. THE CO-OPERATIVE OILMILLS IN DAIvMATTA. Source : Zmave (a.) Die Oelbaugcnossenschafien in Dalmnticn-Oesterreichische Landwirischaftlichc Ge- nossenschaftspresse, Vienna, 15 and 29 April, 13 and 27 May 1915. Genkrai, Remarks. There are sixteen co-operative oilmills in Dalmatia, but three of them are old societies without real vitaUty and we will here therefore treat of only thirteen. The legal constitution of a co-operative oilmill entails the following formalities : i) A meeting for the purpose of foundation which constitutes at the same time the co-operative society's first general meeting ; 2) A report of the foundation meeting and of the first general meet- ing; 3) The drawing - up of by - laws ; 4) A scheme for a budget and for the amortization of the capital in shares ; 5) A joint declaration of adherence by the founder members ; 6) An enqviiry as to the average annual production of the members ; 7) A request signed by the co-operative society for incorporation. An Union of Co-operative Societies {Zadruzni savez) has its premises at Spalato and Ragusa ; and the Lnndeskiiltuyraf for the kingdom of Dal- matia has established at Zara a branch for olive oil, which is supported by the imperial and royal government and which has among other tasks that of selling on conrmission oil remitted to it for such purpose b}'' the co-operative societies. All the co-operative societies have the peculiarity that their by-laws oblige each of their members to belong to them for at least five j'ears from the time at which thev become active. 12 AUSTRIA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION' The following are the thirteen co-operative societies for the production of oil, placed in the order of the date of their foundation and first activity : 1908-1909 : Kali, Preko, Zmau. 1909-1910 : Igrane, Janjina. 1910-1911 Murter, Praskvica (which adhered to the Serbian Federa- tion Savez sepskih privrednih zadruga na Primorju in Ragusa) Pucisce. 1911-1912 : Banj, Briso, Iz Veliki, Tucepi. 1912-1913 : Podgora. The membership of all these societies has gradually risen from 200 at the end of 1908-1909 to about 1,300 at the end of 1913-1914. Corporations — as for instance communal banks — are frequently among the members. The members of the directing body and the superintending council are most frequently numerous — three to eleven ; but three to five would usually suffice. Almost always they are obliged to undergo a preliminary initiation in their functions, a precaution which has in several cases yielded entirely encouraging results. § I. Capitai, of Instali » » 19,320,536 » » « » » » ). 600,000 » » » » » » ), The commission department, which dealt in 1914-1915 with only 1,211,000 bttshels, dealt in the following year with 10,384,156 bushels and in the first three months of the ctirrent year with more than 2,000,000 bushels. RKCHiVT SUCCKSSKS OK ACiKICULTURAL CO-OPERATION The live stock department which began its activity on i April 1914 has since accomplished the business shown by the following table : No. of Cars cousigned No. of Hogs No. of Head No. of Slie<:p S I9I3-I9I4 141 11,000 — — I9I4-I9I5 763 56,603 1,129 805 605,809 1915-191^^ 513 36,624 3,545 659 878,042 I9I6-I9I7 (3 first montljs) 258 6,712 3,493 1,502 305,846 The figures for all the branches of the company's work are equalty interesting. In the first three years 59,222 and 160 carloads of flour and fodder for. live stock and 33,150 and 372 carloads of coal were respectively provided ; and in the first three months of 1916-1917 796 carloads. The quantity of posts provided passed from 75 carloads to 204 in 1915-1916 ; that of twine from 55 carloads in 1914-1915 to 78 in the next 3^ear ; that of lumber and building material from 19 to 42 carloads ; that of wire from 13 to 23 carloads. In the first three months of the present season the com- pany received for sale 40 carloads of fruit produced by members. Finally in these three months the co-operative department has delivered 1,003 carloads of hay, salt, firewood and other necessaries, as against 96 in the farming season of.1913-1914. The co-operative department, of which the principal business has been noted, handled altogether 1,002 cars in the thirteen months ending 31 August 1916 and its total turnover was $749,668. In order to meet the greatly increased demand for coal in the best possible conditions the company has begun to build coal-sheds at points where there are elevators and a demand among local shareholders. This has enabled an accumulation of large quantities of coal and the regulation of its price. The tentative enterprise has met with complete success, orders for 658 carloads to be delivered to farmers having been received on 15 November 1916, the date of the company's last general meeting. The total amount of tlie company's assets on 31 August 1916 was $1,509,496. The profits for the year ending at that date were $282,484. to which mxist be added a balance of $36,229 from the previous year. Out of the total sum $175,000 was paid into the general reserve; a dividend of 8 per cent, was paid to the shareholders; $15,000 provided bonuses for the com- pany's agents ; and the Dominion war tax absorbed $60,000. A balance of more than $23,000 remained to carry over to the next year. 22 CANADA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION § 4. The MANITOBA GRAIN GROWERS* GRAIN COMPANY The year 1915-1916 was from almost every point of view the most satisfactory ever experienced bj^ this compam\ In its ten years of life this company has come to be very powerfvil. When formed on i September 1906 it could count certainly on only a few shareholders ; on 31 April 1916 their number was 18,163. The paid-up capital has risen from S5,ooo to $1,073,000. The profits of the first year were only $790 ; last year they were more than 8570,000. The total quan- tity of grain which the company has handled in the ten years is more than 205 million bushels The total profits amount to §1,488,740 and the total dividends to $550,000. The volume of grain which passed through the compam^'s elevators was, owing to the exceptional crop of a year ago, more than double that handled in the previous 3^ear, namely 14,737,687 bushels as against 6,540,923 bushels. In spite of this increase of about 125 per cent, the working costs increased by only 75 per cent., the total expenses in this de- partment being $437,695 as against $285,897 in 1914-1915. The total revenue was $597,303 as against $292,288 for 1914-1915. Thus this de- partment obtained a profit of $161, 607 as against one of $7,390 for the previous year. The company now owns fourteen elevators in the province of Manitoba. The co-operative department, by sales of machinery and other goods, realized $1,363,591 as against $1,148,128 in the previous year, which gives an increase of 19 per cent. The chief increase was under the head of machinery, of which the sales, those in Calgary being excluded, realized $278,205 as against about $80,000 in 1914-1915. The sales of machinery at Winnipeg and Regina were made up as fol- lows : Tillage tools $102,044.13 Miscellaneous machinery and supplies 83,664.67 Gas engines 13,889.80 Tractors 36,191.39 Vehicles 42,415.79 $278,205.78 The other principal sales effected by the co-operative department were as follows : RECENT SUCCESSES OF AGRICULTURAL CO-OPERATION 2^, Lumber . ^180,410 Millwork .' 23,729 Metal goods 10,756 Builders' supplies 46,120 Twine 520,373 Barbed wire 70,136 Woven wire 53.336 Posts 46,419 Coal 53.249 Flour 8,488 Apples 60,946 These sales realized altogether $1,085,385. The total operations of the co-operative department yielded only a slight profit. The necessity of accumulating large stocks in order to meet demands punctually and to guard against the rise of prices due to the war placed the company in some difficulty. A live stock department was formed during the year. Sales began on I March 1916 : at the end of August 196 carloads of live stock had been handled, and the number handled in September and October was 302. This department is doing educational work in that it shows farmers how to form live stock shipping associations and make the greatest possible pro- fit out of their stock. The total expenses of all kinds' amounted in 1915-1916 to $994,997 and the gross income to $1,566,422. The profit and loss account gives a balance of $572,804, utilized as follows : Dividend of 10 per cent $100,500 War tax 1915-1916 104,381 Reserv^e 217,159 Carried over . . ^ 150,763 On 31 August 1916 the amount of the reserve fund was $600,000. Among the assets invested capital amounts to $801,950 : $225, 682 of this sum being invested in growing timber, and more than $300,000 in town real estate, while the elevators are valued at more than $250,000. There is no doubt that the company is in an excellent position finan- cially. Since it was founded its shareholders have always received a 10 per cent, dividend except in the first year when the dividend was 7 per cent. The shares have risen to 50 per cent, above their nominal value. § 5. The fusion of two great farmers' companies. At the annual general meeting of the Manitoba Grain Growers' Grain Company, held at Winnipeg on 29 November 1916, a ver>- important reso- lution was passed which marks a turning-point in agricultural organiza- 2\ CANADA - eo-()]'IvKAlIOX AM) ASSUCIATKJN tion in Canada. On the proposal of the board of directors the shareholders agreed to the fusion of the companj^ with the Alberta Farmers' Co-operative Elevator Company. The resultant company is known as the United Grain Growers, L,imited. For some j^ears the means of advancing the interests of farmers in the vast region of the west, by grouping together their organizations and thus improving the working of these, had been studied. A year ago an attempt was made to federate the three great companies of which we have spoken, but this was a failure. The board of directors of the Alberta company there- upon proposed to merge their company' and that of Manitoba. The de- tailed steps by which tliis measure ,was accomplished were approv-ed b}' the shareholders of the Alberta compan^^ three weeks before the meeting of the Manitoba company. In accordance with the scheme which was approved the Manitoba Grain Growers' Grain Compan};- will be reorganized on a new basis, that naniel}- of local groups which has already been adopted b^- the Alberta and Saskatchewan companies. Each of these local groups will name delegates who will be sent to the general meetin?, and whose travelling costs will be paid by the company. The shareholders will therefore be much better represented in the general meetings than is the case under the system hitherto followed ; under which the large majorit}^ of shareholders present at the general meetings have been resident within a radius of from sixt}' to a hundred miles of Winnipeg, although the shareholders living in Manitoba are much less than half their total number, 7,500 living in .Saskatchewan and the others in Alberta and British Columbia. The capital in shares of the new company will be 85,000,000 Its bj'-laws will shorth^ be presented for statutory sanction to the par- liament at Ottawa. MISCEIvIvANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. BRITISH INDIA. THE PROGRESS OF CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES IN BARODA STATE. The ±eport of the registrar of Baroda State for 1914-15 shows a very considerable progress made by co-operative societies. The following table gives some details : Kind of Scieties No. of Societies No. of Members Working Capital 1913-1914 1914-1915 1913-1914 I9I4-I9I5* 1913-1914 1914-1915 Central Agricultural .... Non-agricultural . . 3 246 13 2 286 18 176 6,918 655 220 8,071 976 Rs. (I) 128,170 452,006 59,660 Rs. 184,062 536,439 79,719 Total . . . 262 306 7.749 9,267 639,836 800,220 (i) I rupee = is 41/. The registrar states that except in a few places no special efforts were made to organize new societies, but that the people came forward of their own accord, being generally influenced by the successful working of a society in their neighbourhood. The reserve fund of all the societies amounted to Rs. 69,584 as against Rs. 44,500 in the previous year. The amount of loans granted was Ro. 586,566, having increased in the year by Rs. 73,358. Nearly one third of the loans were made for such ordinary agricultural purposes as the pitr- chase of seed or manure and the payment of labourers' wages. Others were for the purchase of cattle and implements, the pa^-ment of land reve- nue and old debts, and trading, industrial and domestic purposes. 26 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The non-credit societies include a milk supply society which suppUes milk to a depot in the town, a milk consumers' societ}- which distributes this milk to residents in the town, and an agricultural society which supplies water for purposes of irrigation. The eighteen non-agricultural societies include five government ser- vants' credit societies, eleven weavers' societies, a municipal scavengers' society and another society of this last type. The registrar acknowledges great help received from the officers of the Revenue Department who were asked, by a special resolution passed by the Honourable Council, to forward the movement. " If ", he states, " the co-operative movement is to be developed, well organized efforts should be made to educate the farmers in the prin- ciples of co-operation. A hand-book on co-operation for use in primary schools has been prepared ". ITAI^Y. I. THE RESOI^UTIONS OF THE NATIONAI, MEETING OF THE AGRICUI^TURAI, CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES AT MII^AN. — La Cooperazione Italiana (Italian Co-opera- tion), organ of the Lega Nazionale delle Cooperative (National I^eague of Co-ojierative Societies), No. 1223, 22 December 1916. On the initiative of the National League of Co-operative Societies there were held at Milan on the 17th and i8th of last December three na- tional meetings of the co-operative societies of consumption, production, labour and agriculture (i). The last-named, which interest us most di- rectly, dealt with agricultural and co-operative colonization, in relation to which the following motion was approved : " i) The meeting reaffirms its preceding resolutions in favour of giving a legal sanction, where the lands of public bodies are concerned, to letting these, on lease or otherwise, or selling them by preference to labouiers' co-operative societies, such prefer- ence being analogous to that given to co-operative labour societies in pub- lic auctions, 2) The meeting declares the need to be urgent and immediate for public works of hydraulics destined to increase the area of land permit- ting of cultivation and to remove one of the more important causes of ill health and of the abandonment of much land. It demands also that there should be agricultural enterprise — internal colonization — the words being understood in their largest sense. The extension of the legislation for the Roman Campagna to all lands in which there is public agricultural enterprise is the first and fundamental action v^hich the meeting demands (i) A few days earlier at Naples the meeting of the co-operative societies of the south was held, and passed resolutions for the constitution of provincial or district federations of the va- rious kinds of co-operative societies, which should help these societies in matters of technique, book-keeping or administration, or legally. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 27 that the government should take, requisitioning uncultivated land and bringing it within such extension. 3) The necessity of increasing agricultu- ral production, the need for employing on agriculture much of the labour wliich in the past emigrated, and the recognized opportunity for reconsti- tuting collective agriculture show the close relationship between internal colonization and co-operative labour and production (collective farms) . Thus wherever the private capitalist might withdraw, because profits were scarce or non-existent, the association of labourers, which w^ouldaim above all at a large gross return to be directly consumed by its members, would have ever}- opportunity to enter and to intensify agriculture. 4) The meeting asks that a large part of the lands which will gradually be bought up, be given to the agricultural co-operative societies. These involve a minimum ini- tial cost, and afford, as compared with land settled for centuries, more em- ployment for labour, and employment both more and more lastingly renumer- ative. For this end the meeting passed a special resolution addressed to the government and the competent bodies. 5) The meeting considered that for the social and economic ends towards which the collective farms were directed, joint and divided management of the lands taken over were equally to be recommended, so long as under one and the other system more intimate and fruitful association linked individual to social activity and vice versa, and so long as there were no lack of technical knowledge or of credit. The essential point was that the land should be given to the labourers, who always had cultivated it and who would cultivate it more and better, for themselves and others, on the day on which they would by their associated efforts derive from it a larger profit ". An order of the day was then approved by which, since the movement for agricultural co-operation was assuming in Italy a steadily growing importance, the National Institute of Credit for Co-operation {Istituto Nazionale di Credito per la Cooperazione) was invited to form an agricultural office which should co-ordinate and direct the action and development of agricultural co-opera- tive societies among labourers. In accordance with thJs vote such an office has already been founded (i) b}^ the institute at Bologna and aims at giving assistance and technical advice to these societies. 2. the; COIvLECTIVE farm of SAN GIOVANNI in CROCE. — L« Cooperazione Ua- liana, Milan, no. 1220, i December 1916. The peasants of San Giovanni in Croce (Cremona), a centre in which class organization, completed by a consumers' co-operative society, has had a noteworthy development, have recently formed a collective farm, underta- king the management of about 800 Cremonese perches (2) of land belonging (i) See La Cooperazione Italiana, Milan, no. 1225, 5 January 1917. (2) I Cremonese perch = 966.45 square yards. 28 INFORMATION REI.ATIXG TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION to the Educational Institutes of Cremona, at a fixed rent of 16.50 liras (i) the perch. To provide live and other stock — more than fifty heads of live stock have already been acquired — the Society has advanced more than fift}^ thousand liras. The, work which will be collectively directed, will be executed mainly by casual labour supplied by the members. Oril}'^ two families have been engaged permanently, and they will have to attend principally to the management of the live stock. The direction of the work is entrusted to an expert, chosen from among the members, who will manage the farm " according to the criteria of the most rigid scrupulosity ". Wages will be fixed according to the contracts locally customary', all rules as to insurance against accidents, disablement and old age being es- pecially ob.served. The administrations of the religious bodies of Cremona have decided to substitute, whenever any of the leases of their landed property expire, a co-operative society of cultivators for the individual farmer. Thiis in this province there is a distinct movement towards collective leases, which should meet with the success obtained by similar enterprises in the prov- inces of Ravenna, Reggio, Emilia, Mantua. 3. THE " SOCIETA ANONIMA COOPERATIVA PER 1,'ESPORTAZIONE DEI PRODOTTI AGRICOIyl " (2) OF JESI IN 1915-1916. — Report for 1915-1916 approved by the general meeting of members on 25 Jmie 1916. Jesi, 1916. This society has two sections, one for the export abroad of agricultu- ral products, the other for the acquisition and the sale to members of ar- ticles useful to agriculture. In 1915-1916 it sold merchandise having an aggregate value of 931,850.66 liras, distributed as follows : Chemical manures liras 498,842.55 Meadow and various seeds » 258,732.87 Anti-cryptogamous substances. ... » 130,658.96 Agricultural and various machines. . » 24,308.68 Fodder for live stock )i 19,307.60 Total .... liras 931,850.66 (i) I lira = 9 ^l^d at par. (2) I^imited lyiability Co-operative Society for the Export of Agricultural Products. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION .29 As regards the section for export this could not discharge its function owing to the embargo on foreign export. The cauliflowers produced were however sold at home in the markets of Upper Italy, to which 715,790 of them or 85 car-loads, having a total value of 60,534 liras, were sent. In the same year a new dryer for cocoons was installed by the societ}^, so that the two driers wliich now exist fully satisfy the demands of members. The society's sales have increased steadily, having realized in 1910-1911 a va- lue of 148,369 liras, in 1911-1912 one of 850,976 liras, in 1912-13 one of 1,112,959 liras, in 1913-1914 one of 1,295,731 liras, and in 1914-15 one of 1,234,136 liras. The society's capital reached at the and of the year in question 159,218.82 liras, made up as follows : capital in shares 84,250 liras; ordi- nary reserve fund 55,540.49 liras ; extraordinary reserve fund 19,428.33 Hras. The net profits — 55,468.80 hras — were distributed as follows : a) to the shares 5 per cent, of the paid-up capital, 4,205.90 liras ; b) to the orfUnary reserve 70 per cent, of the residue, 35,884.66 liras ; c) to the purchasers 20 per cent., 10,252.76 Hras ; and finally d) 10 per cent, was set aside to provide for new initiative, 5,126.38 Hras. The society was able to reach such results thanks to the help obtained from local credit agencies, particularly the Banca Popolare Cooperativa (Popular Co-operative Bank). 4. THE ACTIVITY OF THE OFFICE OF I^EGAI, ADVICE OF THE " I.EGA NAZIONAI^E DEI/I^E COOPERATIVE ". — La Cooperazione Italiana, organ of tliis league, Milan, no. 1225, 5 Jauuarj' 1917. Among the multiple services rendered by this Milanese National League of Co-operative Societies to its federated societies one of the best organ- ized and certainl}^ the most useful is that of affording legal advice. Tliis service is entrusted to an expert who has summarized the activity of his office in the following table : ■ ^ No. of Affairs dealt with Written Opin- ions Oral Consul- tations lyocal Enquir- ies News- paper Articles Co-operative Societies Mu- Year Con- sump- tion I,abour Agricul- tural Build- ing Mixed tual 1912 1316 1097 160 51 770 293 37 58 37 127 1913 1247 1068 179 — — • 628 371 — 68 — 137 1914 1269 1 103 139 10 17 634 296 86 38 86 157 1915 u68 969 176 7 23 534 319 43 73 — 142 1916 859 744 100 — 15 365 204 37 45 — 93 30 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION It is seen that in spite of the difficulties of the present time the National lyeagtie of Co-operative Societies neglects nothing in order to continue its work of helping and safeguarding the interests of these societies which now number more than 7,000. 5. THE FORMATION OF THE) " SOCIETA DEGI,I ENOTECNICI ITAI^IANI ". — Com- municated by the Society. On the basis of the votes of the National Congress of Experts in Wine, held last summer at Voghera, this " Society of Italian Experts in Wine", has been definitely formed. It has headquarters at Caselmonferrato and is intended to include all licentiates of the higher technical schools of wine production in Alba, Avelhno, Cagliari, Catania and Conegliano. The so- ciety's aim, bej'ond that of defending trade interests, is to promote and favour the technical and economic progress of viticulture and wine pro- duction in Italy, where these industries represent more than seven thou- sand million liras of invested capital and employ more than two million citizens. * * * 6. THE DEVEI589 )) » » » 1914 1.369 i. e. an increase of 220 Insured value in 1915 40,842,638 » » » 19-^4 34,332,502 i. e. an increase of 6,510,136 Assessments in 1915 582,158 » » 1914 548,785 i. e. an increase of 33,373 The cases of payment of indemnities numbered 317 and their amount was 1,162,938 francs. 2. Insurance against Mortality among Live Stock. — For the fifteen federated funds for insurance against mortality among live stock the re- sults for 1915 were as follows : Number of policies 197 Value of insured animals 1,193,475 francs Assessments 33,388 » Indemnities 28,186 » Percentage of assessments constituted by indemnities 84 % (i) I franc = 9 ^/g d at par. 4 44 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 3. Insurance against Fire. 1912 1913 1914 1915 Number of policies . . . . 342 t,o86 1,192 i>495 francs francs francs francs Insured value 5,488,043 19,112,523 23,899,851 37,364,682 Net assessments 45.59^ 146,788 174,262 281,419 Indemnities paid .... 31,938 83,147 83-454 120,245 Percentage of assessments constituted by indem.- nities 70 % 57 % 48 % 43 % FRANCE. THE MUTUAI, AGRICUIvTURAI, FIRE INSURANCE SOCIETY OF THE EAST ON i JANUARY igi6. — Annular dc la Miitualitr. ct de la Cooperation agricolcs., Paris, sini^ issue of 1916. On I January' 1916 the Mutual Agricultural Fire Insurance Society o^ the East reinsured 849 communal fuiids, distributed among the funds of the district as follows : Haute-Marne 438 Vosges 131 Jtira 76 Haute-Saone 73 Meurthe-et-Moselle 62 Doubs 52 Saone-et-Iyoire 17 The number of these communal societies increased progressively, in- fluenced b}'' the great advantages they afford to agricultural labourers. The following table shows this development, of which the regularity is wor- thy of emphasis : On I December 1905 10 societies On I January 1906 115 » » 1907 425 » » 1908 502 » )) 1909 560 » >) 1910 637 » « 1911 762 » » 1912 778 » » 1913 815 » 1914 848 » » 1915 849 1) » 1916 849 » IXl'ORMATIOX RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 45 The number of members effectively insured is proportionate to the number of policies, which has successively reached the following levels: On I January 1906 21 1907 1,824 » 1908 3,522 1909 5,325 )! 1910 7>i9i >■ 1911 9.492 1912 12,140 1913 14,617 » 1914 17,252 1915 ^19,536 )) 1916 21,143 policies The capital guaranteed by the mutual societ}^ has increased like the number of the insured, that is to say in proportion to the subscribed po- licies. This capital, which is the chief asset of the 20,000 members, reached annually the following amounts : On I January 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 283,100 -14,901,025 29,592,477 44,436,428 60,872,485 79,944,485 101,742,995 123,585,836 146,113,616 168,186,436 184,829,266 fr. The net premiums received were as follows In 1905 In 1906 In 1907 In 1908 In 1909 1910 1911 In 1912 In 1913 In 1914 1915 In In In 45-75 12,673.25 32,658.75 50,467-58 68,338.95 89,120.12 112,841.40 138,890.86 164,435.60 188,853.60 207,573-30 fr. 46 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT The amount of indemnities paid for fires was : In 1905 0.00 fr In 1906 11,543.70 In 1907 25,257.40 In 1908 39,287.80 In 1909 20,485.45 In 1910 36,656.45 In 1911 61,387.50 In 1912 43,069.25 In 1913 68,875.50 In 1914 150,573-30 In 1915 94.133-94 ITALY. I. THE PROPOSAI^S OF SENATOR CONTI'S EAWFORCOMPEEEING THE INSURANCE OF EAND AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF PEASANTS' EABOUR. — Senato del Regno. Legislatura XXIV 1st session 1913-1916. Documenti : no. 317. In the sessions of 12 and 16 December 1916, that is to say ahnost sim- ultaneously, two proposed laws for rendering insurance against the acci- dents of agriculture compulsory were considered and developed in the Se- nate and the Chamber of Deputies (i). One of these is due to the initiative of the deputies Borromeo, Venino and Belotti, the other to that of Senator Conti. We have already dealt with the former (2). Although the ideas of the proposer of the second scheme are fortunately already well known we will recall its basic principles : (i) In connection with the problem of insurance against the accidents of agricultural la- bour the General Confederation of labour recentlj- passed the following order of the daj- : " The directing council of the General Confederation of Eabour affirms anew its previously expressed wishes as to the necessity of a]complete insurance of labour against sickness, disablement and old age, in order to complete the accident insurance. The council asks the government to promulgate the promised law as to agricultural accidents, and in it to take into account the chief desires expressed on various occasions by the organizations, namety : a) that insurance be com- pulsory and protect without distinction all labourers on the soil and all agricultuial en- terprise attach'ng to H, 'ncludmg small proprietor cultivators ; b) that the right of agricultural labourers to insurance against temporary' disablement be reccgnized ; c) that the insurance be entrusted to mixed and obligatory unions and completed bj' reinsurance with the National Accidents Fund ; d) that when the law as to agricultural accidents is promulgated labour be given juster repre- sentaticn on the council and committee of the National Accidents Fimd ». Other desires for compulsory insurance against agricultural accidents were recently formu- lated in the meeting of representatives of the organization of the agricultural labourers of the province of Reggio and Emilia — who asked that such insurance should be entmsted to the National Accidents Fund — and by the agricultural commission of the Eeague of Socialist Communes. (2) International Review of Agricultural Economics, June 1916, pp. 61 et seq. INFORMATIOX RELATING TO IXSURANCE AND THRIFT 47 i) Insurance against the accidents of labour is made a burden on land as constituting an inherent obligation of iDroprietorship. But this principle is neither absolute nor general. Exceptions are made in favour of a property held on lease, in the case of which the obligation and liabi- Hty to insure devolve on any lessee who has undertaken cultivation in which the proprietor is not interested. 2) Insurance is entirely the responsibility of the proprietor if he cultivate his land or realize its value directly. It is the responsibility of the lessee if the land be let. If the land be granted on the system of me- tayage or another profit sharing S3^stem, the costs of insurance are divided between the proprietor and the occupier or metayer, the division being equal if products be shared equalh'. If all products be not shared exactly equalty, two thirds of the insurance premium are charged to the landowner and one third to the metayer or occupier. 3) Insurance, saving in the exceptional cases enumerated under 4), is applicable without distinction to all agricultural labourers, including the peasants — men and women — who are constantly or temporarily employed on any work indispensable to tilth, agricultural production and farming, including such works as, owing to their necessary connection with and dependence on the production of a property, cannot be considered to be other than agricultural, and those habitually or exceptionally practised in dwellings, farms, dairies, presses, cellars^ cisterns, and every other kind of labour of an agricultural character, if it be indispensable to tilth and agri- cultural production. 4) Insurance is not compulsorv^ for peasants of either sex under thir- teen and over seventy years old. Such peasants if employed on works al- ready contemplated by the law on accidents in industries and enterprises (unified text of 31 January 1904 no. 51) will still be insured according to the terms of that law. 5) There can be no indemnifications except in the case of accidents which result in death or permanent disability, entire or partial, due to a traumatic cause consequent on work. 6) Xotioe must be given of everj- accident by the victim or his fam- ily, within five days of its occurrence, to the owner or lessee of the pro- perty. If such notice be not thus given the injury will be taken not to have been caused by the work, 7) A workman who is the victim of a simple accident must, if request- ed to do so by the insuring establishment, remain in a hospital for the time needed to determine the causes of the accident, in order to hasten his cure and diminish the accident's consequences. If he refuse unjustifia- bly to do this he loses his right to any indemnity. 8) The amount of the indemnity is 2,500 lires (i) in the cases both of death and of permanent and absolute disablement, but in the case of death it is reduced to 1000 liras if the deceased be not married and have no family to maintain, and is paid to his heirs. (i) I lira = 9 3/g (/. at par. 48 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 9) A request for the revision of an indemnity is not acceded to unless it be proved that the first pa3'ment was made erroneously or unless the vic- tim's physical condition be further modified as a result of the accident. Such request ma}^ be made only once, and not earlier than three months — or one month in the case of a death — after the pa^'ment of the indemnitj-. 10) Action to obtain the indemnity must be taken within six months after the occurrence of the accident as determined by the certificate and the judgement of the magistrate. 11) The principle of free choice of an insuring establishment is main- tained. It is included in the law already mentioned, as to the accidents of industrial labour. 12) The extent of the property in relation to its various crops, all of which must be mentioned and classified in the rules, is taken as a basis for fixing the insurance premium. For small properties having an area of less than half a hectare (i) the premium is halved. 13) The determination of disputes as to the nature and the impor- tance of the consequences of an accident is reserved to a college of arbiters. * * * 2. THE MUTUAL INSURANCE OF LIVE STOCK INTENDED FOR BUTCHERY. — A. PiROCCHi in La Mutualitd Agraria, no. 30, Rome, 30 November 1916. In Italy since the law on sanitation of 22 December 1888 has been ap- plied, an attempt has been made to compensate for looses consequent on the sequestration of butchers' meat, by insuring the animals with associations constituted on the principle of mutuality, by forming municipal insurance associations, or by insuring them with private joint stock societies. A great association formed for this purpose was active in North Ital^^ but failed and went into liquidation. On the other hand small societies, each of them active in a more or less limited sphere, as for instance a slaiighterhouse, have had better results. The most important of these are the slaughter- houses of Milan, Turin, Rome, Mantua, Bergamo, Bologna, Florence and Naples. It will certainly be useful to show the organization and results of one of them, that of Milan, the growth of which is apparent from the fol- lowing figures. (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 49 No. Receipts Expend-ture Indemnities Paid Annual Profit Year of Members liras liras liras liras 1902 ... 25 154.896-35 114,896.35 98,271.20 40,000.00 1903 — 155.372-93 127,864.41 102,150.78 27.508.52 1904 — 153.364-35 124,854.05 101,355.09 28,510.30 1905 — 188,384.50 170.168.55 ■ 140,304.46 18,215.95 1906 — 191,174.09 166,868.24 139.670.37 24.305-85 1907 — 196.237.57 158.022.52 132,311.90 38.215.05 1908 — 187,498.82 167,079.23 141,286.45 20,419.59 1909 — 173.892.97 149,235.96 116,624.23 24,657.01 I9IO 265 179,156.02 1 150,093.78 124,643.90 1 1 1 29,062,24 This association comprises butchers, live stock dealers and dealers on commission. The members undertake to insure with the society all their live stock intended to be butchered. Insurance was a,t first limited to ani- mals attacked by tuberculosis or anthrax but was extended to cover all animals sequestrated in consequence of a statement that they were affected hy any disease. Premiums are fixed at the following rates : oxen, i lira ; foreign cows and bulls, 3 liras ; home cows and bulls, 5 liras ; thin oxen, 3.50 liras ; calves, o.io lira. The society's property is made up of admission fees, insur- ance premiums, the results of selling the remains of animals, interest on invested sums, repayments of expenses chargeable to insured persons and the reserve fund. The admission fee is 25 liras together with a premium annually determined by the members' general meeting, according to the amount of the reserve fund as shown by the last balance-sheet. The reserve fund is made up of a determined part of each year's balance, certain profits prescribed because they have not been withdrawn within a year of the day on which they became withdrawable, and premiums paid in addi- tion to the admission fee. Indemnities are paid when a declaration of the sequestration is delivered to the slaughterhouse's veterinary office. From this moment the societ}' becomes the owner of the animal, and is responsible for all tolls, costs of slaughter and destruction and knacker's fees. The net profits are distributed as follows: one quota to the reserve fund {this was during the first two j^ears 50 per cent, of the annual net profits); 3 per cent to the manager ; 2 per cent, to the staff ; the remainder to the members in shares proportionate to the premiums they have paid, if the amount of the sums repaid to them because of casualties do not surpass the total amount of the premiums. The association is represented b}^ the members' meeting, the adminis- trative council and the manager. For the annual inspection of accounts there are three commissaries for the accounts and two deputies for them. To decide disputes there is a commission of five members of whom three do not belong to the society. Such are the fundamental principles on which this association is orga- nized and on which it works. It enjoys the favour not only of those interested in it but also of the communal authorities. 50 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT As for municipal insurance this has been profitabl}^ introduced in a vohmtary form in a slaughterhouse of the Abruzzi, that of Aquila. It has two branches — insurance against losses caused by leprosy among pigs and against losses of cattle caused by ictherus, tuberculosis etc. The premiums for cattle are: 5 liras for milch cows, i lira for bulls, oxen and cows not be- longing to a race of milch cows, and 0.60 lira for weaned and 0.2a lira for unweaned calves. For pigs the premium is i lira. For each head of cattle the communal fund pays an indemnity cal- culated according to the weight of the four quarters at market prices, less 0.15 lira a kilogramme, in the case of milch cows and o.io lira in the case of other cattle. As for pigs the fund pays the amount of the animal's full price, less 5 liras in the case of a boar and less 12 liras in other cases. Animals for which indemnities have been paid of course remain the property of the communal administration. There are special provisions against frauds. Lastty joint stock societies have also been constituted in Italy for this object. They are not numerous however and their activity is usually unimportant. One of them — perhaps the most important in virtue of the funds of which it disposed — was recently dissolved after having attempted to extend its sphere over most of the kingdom. * 3. THE RUIZES FOR THE DISTRICT OFFICES OF AGRICUIyTURAl^ MUTUAI^ITY. — La Mutualitd Agraria, organ of the IstiUito Nazionale per la Mutnalita Agraria, no. 2, Rome, 20 January 191 7. Recently, as is well known, various district offices of agricultural mu- tuality were founded in Italy, at Turin, Genoa, Florence, Mantua, Reggio in Calabria and Palermo. The Istituto Nazionale per la Mutitalita Agraria, which was the promoter of these ofhce^, has now thought it opportune to draw up special rules for their use and the use of those which \\ould gradually be formed in other districts. We resume the fundamental principles of these rules : The constitution of a district office of agricultural mutuality is first of all accordant with an agreement between the local administrations and the National Institute of Agricultural Mutuality already cited. This agree ment specifies the method of working. Its aim is : a) to multiply mutual funds for insurance against mortality among live stock, to assist their administrative and technical installation, and to give them an impulse to federation and reinsurance ; h) to disseminate, especially among small farmers and small pro- prietors, knowledge of the hygiene of rearing live stock and the use of asso- ciation with a view to zootechnical improvement ; (1) I kilogramme = 2.2 lbs. INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT c) to popularize the rules for the constitution and the good working of co-operative and mutual institutions (mutual insurance against losses from hail, fire, accidents of labour etc.), and to disseminate thrift and popular education in the country ; d) to organize carefully the collection of complete statistics as to mutual societies and data relative to their working. The action of the office extends into every district and is exercised ; i) by oral propaganda, 2) by the circulation of pamphlets of propaganda, 3) in pursuit of its aim, that of determining the formation, installation and administrative control of mutual societies. It will enter into relations with the itinerant chairs of agriculture and the authorities and institutions which can best assist its action. The resources necessary'- to its work are formed of the quota paid for participation by the institutions belonging to it (provinces, communes, savings funds, popular banks, agricultural unions, etc.) by the State's contributions and by other eventual receipts. The work of the office is directed by a managing commitee composed of five members chosen from the delegates of institutions making grants and from the best known local persons, besides the representatives of the Ministries of the Interior and of Agriculture. This commission chooses from its own number a president, a vice-president and a secretary. Its task is to see that the funds, of which we have already spoken, are regularly employed. The office is entrusted to the care of a director, who should be a specialist in agricultural subjects or a veterinary surgeon and who is nominated by the National Institute of Agricultural Mutuality. 4. A NEW MUTUAL INSURANCE SOCIETY AGAINST THE ACCIDENTS OF AGRI- CULTURE. Pending the law on the compulsory insurance of peasants a mutual society for insurance against the accidents of agriculture (i) has recently been formed at Rome under the name of " Terra Italica ". The initiative was due to the sjnidicate for the insurance of woodcutters and the society has gained the adherence of most of the members of that syndicate and of many farms in the various districts of Italy. * 5. ITALIAN SAVINGS ON 30 JUNE 1916. We take the following data from the Esposizione finanziaria fatta alia Camera dei Deputati nella Seduta del 14 Decemhre 1916, the report made by (i) For the other mutual funds for iusurance against the accidents of agriculture active in Italy see International Review of Agricultural Economics, January 191 7, pp. 43-55- 52 IXFORMATIOX RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT the Minister of the Treasury, Signer Paolo Carcano, on the situation with regard to savings deposits on current account and in interest-bearing bonds on 30 June 1916 : Savings Deposits on Current Account and in Interest-bearing Bonds on 30 June 1916. Issuing Institutions : Deposits on current account bearing interest .... 504,660,392 liras Institutions of Ordinary Credit : Number of existing institutions 121 Subscribed capital 566,381,030 Paid-up capital 548,872,935 « Deposits : Ordinary and in interest-bearing bonds 553.549.677 Savings 354,204,069 » Popular Banks: ISTumber of existing banks 323 Subscribed capital 81,284,410 » Paid-up capital 80,526,175 » Deposits : Ordinary and in interest-bearing bonds 230,309,310 » Savings . 477,632,799 » 707,942,109 Other Co-operative Banks Number of existing banks 311 Subscribed capital 43,292,269 Paid-up capital 42,749,718 • Deposits : Ordinary' and in interest-bearing bonds 172,991,152 Savings 358,699,802 531,690,954 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 53 Ordinary Savings Banks: Savings deposits : Credit of depositors 2,678,088,923 liras Deposits on current account and in interest-bearing bonds : Credit of depositors and amount of bonds in circulation 226,971,583 » 2,905,060,506 Savings Banks and Postal Banks: Number of books . 6,382,949 Credit of depositors 1,987,639,997 Monti di Pieta (Pawning institutions) : Ordinary deposits and interest-bearing bonds .... 120,285,037 » Savings deposits 125,081,842 » 245.366,879 Rural Funds ; Various trust deposits 112,335,769 » Summary. Ordinar\- Deposits 1,808,767,151 liras Savings iJeposits 5,981,347,432 > Deposits in Rural Funds 112,335,769 » Total . . . 7,902,450,352 )' Thus Italian savings amounted altogether on 30 June 1916 to 7,902,450,352 liras, as against 6,490,690,179 liras on 30 June 1910. The greater part of the amount — about five thousand millions — entered, as appears from the table we have just given, the ordinary and postal sav- ings banks. The total sum of the deposits in the popular banks, the rural funds and the other co-operative banks — 1,351,968,832 liras — was also notable and shows what confidence these institutions inspire. 54 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURAJi^CE AND THRIFT RUSSIA. FINNISH SOCIETIES FOR INSURANCE AGAINST MORTALITY AMONG LIVE STOCK IN 1913. — Bidrag till Finlands officielle statistik : Forsakringsinsptktorens berattelse angaende de lokala brandstods-och kreatursforsakringsforeningarnas verksamhet under ar 1913 {Official Statistics of Finland : Report on the Condition of Bailiwick and Parish So- cieties for Insurance against Fire and Mortality among Live Stock in 1913) Helpingfors, 1915 At the end of 1913, 121 societies for insurance against mortality among live stock were active within spheres of less area than a government. They were distributed in the various governments as follows : Government of Nyland 5 » » Abo and Bjorneborg. . . 7 » 1) Tavastehus 3 « » Viborg 25 » » Saint ]\Iichael 5 )) » Kuopio 5 » » Vasa 59 » » Uleaborg. ........ 12 Total ... 121 The number and value of the insured animals were at the end of 1913 as follows Horses 34,162 valued at 12,026,073 marks (i) Horned cattle 40,260 » » 4,497,972 » Small live stock. ... — » » 23,673 » Total . . . 16,547,718 « If to these figures be added those relevant to the four societies which are active throughout the country, we find that animals were insure against mortality as follows at the end of 1913 : Horses 62,423 _ valued at 23,344,011 marks Horned cattle 57>845 » » 7,115,797 . » Small live stock. ... — » » 23,673 » Total. . . . 30,483,481 » Of the total number of horses 20.2 per cent, were insured, of that of horned cattle only 4.9 per cent. Of the local societies thirt3^-three insvxred onl}'' horses and four only horned cattle, the remaining eighty-four insuring both horses and horned cattle. From the point of view of the importance of the risks covered these societies can be grouped as follows, the figures having reference to the num- ber of societies : (1)1 Finnish mark = 9 ^/g (/ at par. INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT 55 Year Societies insuring less than 50,000 marks Societies insuring from 50,000 to 100,000 marks Societies insuring from 100,000 to 200,000 marks Societies insuring from 200,000 to 500,000 marks Societies insuring 500,000 marks or more Num- Per- Num- Per- Num- Per- Num- Per- Num- Per- ber centage Ijer centage ber centage ber centage ber centage 1905 10 17.9 13 23.2 19 33-9 II 19.6 3 5-4 1906 18 237 17 22.4 27 35-5 12 15-8 2 2.6 1907 14 17-5 19 23.8 32 40.0 13 16.2 2 2.5 1908 16 18.8 17 20.0 31 36.5 19 22.4 2 2.3 1909 16 17-5 17 18.7 35 38.5 20 22.0 3-3 1910 22 22.0 22 22.0 30 30.0 23 23.0 3 30 1911 22 21.0 25 23.8 35 33-3 20 19.0 3 2.9 1912 35 22.5 27 243 37 35-4 19 17. 1 3 2.7 19 1 3 27 22.3 33 27-3 38 31-4 20 16.5 3 2.5 The percentage of accidents was 1.94 in the case of the insured horses, 1.33 in that of the insured horned cattle. Indemnities amounted to 1.26 per cent, of the insured value in the case of horses, i per cent, in that of the horned cattle. The average indemnity paid was 225.49 marks for a horse, 80.65 marks for a head of horned cattle. The following table resumes the data on this head for the ten years for which there is authentic statistical material : Number of A.ccidents Horses Percentage Cattle Percentage Indemnity per 100 marks of insured capital Horses Marks Cattle Marks Indemnity per Accident Horses Marks Cattle Marks 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 I91O I91I 1912 1913 1.67 1.77 1.60 1.63 1.65 1.74 2.03 2.31 2.21 1.94 68 94 86 45 19 46 26 25 52 33 1. 10 0.96 1. 11 0.97 r.ii 1.16 1.20 1.68 1-37 1.26 1. 00 1.08 1.18 1. 00 0.87 1. 00 0.93 0.97 1.06 1. 00 230.03 212.53 229.73 195-64 224.69 226.70 204.80 299.22 214.05 22549 55-43 52.68 5596 62.25 68.21 65.20 71.30 76.56 71.08 80.65 56 INFORMATION RELATING TO INSURANCE AND THRIFT The premiums paid in 1913 were as follows : For the insurance of horses specially. 112,014 niarks " » » « horned cattle » . 28,241 » » reserve fund 7.224 » and generally 95.852 » Total . . . 243,331 » This sum constitutes 1.53 per cent, of the average amount of the in- sured capital during the year. Other receipts and interest etc. brought the societies 19,970 marks or 0.13 per cent, of such average amount. The receipts were thus altogether 263,301 niarks or 1.66 per cent, of the average amount of the insured capital. Of this sum the following sums were spent : On indemnities 188,612 marks or 1.19 per cent, of the insured capital On costs of administration 27,693 » » 0.17 » » » » » On increasing reserve fund . . 10,778 » « 0.07 » » '■ >» » On other ex- penses . . . 13,184 » » 0.08 » » )» » )> Total . . . 240,267 » » 1. 51 )) » » » » There was thus a net profit of 23,040 marks. Costs of administration reached 11. 4 per cent, and other . expendi- ture — costs of organization, interest, etc. — 5.4 per cent, of the premiums received. The balance-sheets of the societies showed at the end of the year, when the amount of engagements had been deducted, an excess on the re- ceipts side amounting to 90,984 marks or 5.50 marks for everj^ 1000 marks of insured capital. Part III: Credit ALGERIA. CREDIT FOR COI.ONIZATION IN ALGERIA SOURCE : AvENOL (j.) : I^es Banques Algeriennts et la Banque de I'Algerie (Algerian Banks and the Bank of Algetia) in Revue dcs Sciences politiqiies, 3rd. Series, 31st. year. Vol. XXXVI. — III. Paris, 15 December igi6. The considerable economic development of Algeria in the last ten years is proof of the remarkable effort which colonists have made in the domain of agriculture, and also of the perfect appropriateness of the financial me- thods which have been employed to support agriculture by providing it with necessar}- credit. From 1901 to 1911 Algeria's foreign trade doubled, being represented in 1913 by the sum of fifteen hundred million francs (i). The success of this effort was only rendered possible by the support given to colonists b}' the bank*:. The three principal of them are the Banque de I'Algerie, which has a privileged issue, and two private houses — the Credit Fonder d'Algene and the Compagnie Alger ienne. M. J. Avenol, from whom we borrow the chief data contained in this short study, remarks that the two generations following on the conquest did not experience hindrance and uncertainty in vain. Algeria has become a countr}^ of bold, enterprising colonists, having faith in the future of the land and the technique and traditions necessary to deriving profit from its (1) I franc = 9^5 '^^ ^t par. ALGERIA - CREDIT soil. The colonists are however short of capital : they need credit and therefore the collaboration of the banks. The banks have, like the settlers, profited by the lessons of an experimental half century and have also tak- en on a distinct^ Algerian character. In the midst of their business dif- ficulties they have worked out their methods and become aware of the part they have to pla}-. As years pass their functions become more and more im- portant. Agricultural wealth grows with increasing rapidity and receives from credit increasingly powerful aid. We have said that the foreign trade of Algeria has doubled in ten 3'ears. The value of the paper held b}' the three chief banks has been multipUed by five in the same period and this fact is the measure of the part the banks have taken in colonization — a part which has been preponderant. § I. The character of the credit afforded to coloxizatiox. The problem of credit in Algeria is posed as follows : " It is easy for colonists to procure land, but only uncultivated, bush- grown land, or — what is worse — land overgrown with deep-rooted len- tisks and palm-trees. To bring it under cultivation, erect buildings, buy machines and build up stock — all this asks for more than hard work and courage. And when a well worked farm has arisen out of the Arabian hied, circulating funds are still needed, to cover the costs of the seeds, the maintenance and the harvest which allow the annual course of agricultural labour. Must the colonist from the outset have all the capital which he has to invest ? Will he be able to contract for a long-term loan, like a French landowner who wishes to improve his property' ? " Land credit as understood in France did not seem to be adapted to a new country Uke Algeria. What after all is a mortgage of bush-land worth ? A borrower has, as in all countries where the value of the soil has not been realized, no assets but his chances and his hope. It has been deemed im- prudent therefore to trust him with capital of which he would be master for a long period. Moreover he cannot make his farm in a single year but brings his efforts to success gradually. It is enough to grant him every season advan- ces proportionate to the harvests which invented capital ma}' be expected to produce. The risks of loss are thus diminished, and progressive efforts can be helped by successive advances for short terms. Thus the creditor follows the fortunes of the debtor step b\' step. Each period brings him a reward. Each j^ear his security is strengthened b^' the increased value of the property, and his mortgage, if he have one, has eventualh' a firm basis. This transaction may be compared with that which enables a trader to open a credit account : there is no single grant of one loan but a series of successive operations. But thej- are timed more slowly than in the trader's case in accordance with the seasons — advances being granted when the season opens and repaid at harvest-time. CREDIT FOR COI.ONIZATION 59 These short loans are banking business and form indeed the chief bu- siness of the Algerian banks, which are above all agricultural banks. Their paper cetainly includes many ordinan,' commercial bills which represent realized transactions and settlemefits of debts. But it consists largely of these loan titles which are in the traditional form of bills maturing in three months, there being a tacit agreement that they are twice renewable in order to bring them into line with the farming cycle. It is seen that personal credit is here concerned. Naturally the banks, each in its own way, seek to surround their debtors with a network of se- curities ; but these, excellent though they be, are only accessory, as appears from what we have already said. The chief dependence is on a just esti- mate of an}' colonist admitted to the benefits of credit. The paper of the Algerian banks represents therefore in part short-term loans, certainh- recoverable with good management, but not maturing as rigorously as ordinary banking notes because their realization depends on the sale of the harvest. § 2. The sources of the capital assigned to agricultural credit. Obviously the banks cannot find all the capital required by their bu- siness in Algeria, but must supply themselves abroad, that is to say in France. In what form do they acquire this capital — as capital, shares, deposits at sight or financial bills — and in what proportion ? The very special character of their business does not leave their choice entireh' free. They cannot count on that uninterrupted series of graduated receipts which gives the desired liquidity to thf paper of French banks. Many of their advances are tied up for from eight to nine months in a year. From the beginning of the agricultural year the number so im- mobilized increases until the harvest releases all of them together. A new financial effort is then necessary. Harvest-time, the single period in which revenue is received, opens up a series of numerous settlements — purchases of harvested products, payment of wages, payments for transport and various acquisitions, repayments. Tliis accumulation of payments within so short a time gives rise to a considerable need of money. The banks must meet it, for the purchasers of the harvest, with whom the movement starts, come to them for circulating funds in the form of seasonal credit. This progessive and uniformly periodic nature of obligations can- not accommodate itself to resources which are too fluid and unstable: banks subject to such obligations cannot run the risk of being suddenh- forced to make large repayments.Therefore they must follow the example of business banks and diminish their margin of liabilities by working with a large capital in shares. But where can they find complementary resources in a countr>' poor in capital ? On what reservoir can they draw- in order to feed the stream of their business ? Is it possible that an agricul- tural country, which has financial resources insufficient for its own needs, can escape from strict subjection to the European banks, by avoiding the 6o AI^GEKIA - CREDIT too direct effects of the reaction from international situations and tight money-markets, and by acquiring, if not independence, at least a certain financial autonomy? Algeria seems to be in the privileged position which allows of all this. Its two great private banks, the Credit Fonder d'Algerie and the Compagnie Alger ienne, have in France not only the headquarters of their respective companies but also agencies. They act as French banks and have succeeded in obtaining depositing clients. This direct participation in the resources of the short-term capital 'market is a great force : it enables them to divide their debt among numerous depositors, almost all of whom are without the preoccupations of professional finance and have markedlj' regular habits and needs. These banks are thus directly connected with French capitalists and the constant level of their resources is the better assured to them. But these deposits, although they are abundant and relatively stable, have not the needed elasticity. In order to have resources at co:nmand during the eight or ten months of the progressive immobilization of their advances the banks must be able to rediscount their paper. For this thej^have locally the support of a bank which helps them to imdertake new operations before those in course have been complete^ realized. The Banqite de I'Algerie, being master of its issues, allows rediscount, and thus gives to the other banking houses the opportunity of making settlements on the volume of their business, and provides them with the resources in credit and specie which are required by the needs of the harvest. § 3. The role of the baxoue de i,'ai,gerie. The Banque de I'Algerie has been privileged for sixty-five years to issue notes ; and its activity and prosperity have increased considerabh', espe- cially in the last fifteen years. Its powers are large, and its methods are based rather on unhampered experience than on rules. No cover is com- pulsory for its issues ; it discounts bills and gives notes in exchange for them. Its circulation therefore varies with the necessities of the moment, is en- larged when the need of money is considerable and narrowed in times of stagnation.lt is of course limited by a legal maximum. The bank accepts for discount bills bearing two signatures, and if it undertakes rediscount it seeks especially for a direct clientele. . It is easy to understand that in order to associate itself with the activity of the country the bank must not in these circumstances merely accept commercial bills, but must be above all an agricultural bank and make advances. If it be profitable to a new country that its fiduciary circulation should be important among its necessary means of credit, the ability' of a bank issu- ing notes to over-develop its business constitutes on the other hand a grave danger. It is therefore above all necessary to excliide credit granted for motives of complaisance and to allow credit to have a bearing only on gen- uine business. At the price of continued experience the Banque de I'Al- gerie has acquired an extremely sure technique. This fiduciary circula- CREDIT FOR COI.ONIZATION 6l tion, linked without rigidit}' to the course of its business, therefore pro- vides it with a precious instrument. Since gold does not circulate in the colony, owing to the fact that the balance of trade with the mother-country is against it and to native hoarding, the currency is exclusiveh' Algerian. The notes are payable to the bearer at sight in silver. None the less there is exchange between Algeria and P'rance, the per- fect equilibrium between the two monetary systems being due to a curious mechanism created by an administrative convention. The Banque de I' Alger ie has opened at the Treasury a current account into which agents make payments and whence they make withdrawals. Owing to the costs of military occupation public expenditure in Algeria has always exceeded local resources. The Treasury would therefore have had frequently to reinforce the credit it gianted, had not this been accomplished automatically and simply b}- a utilization of sums placed at the Treasury's disposal by Algerians for the payment of their foreign debts. The concentration of these in the Banque de I'Algerie compelled this bank to become the inter- mediary for pa^'ments in France, charging a moderate commission. In virtue of this convention the bank must remit a bill on the home Treasury, on demand, to anyone paying its amount, and such bill is covered by the bank's credit account. As for Algerian debtors they receive for their own bank notes a value which can be realized in France at par. In recent years this system of direct remittances has been largely replaced by postal or- ders which accrue to the Treasury's account bj^ the medium of post-office receivers. Postal administration does no more than see that its receipts are paid into the Treasury's current account at the Banque de I'Algerie, and the latter is responsible for settling Algerian debts to the home country. From 1904 to 1913 the issues of the post-office exceeded the amount of the payments in the form of postal orders by fifteen hundred million francs, for which sum the bank became the Treasury's debtor. This debt did not accumulate for the credit balance of the Treasury remained con- stantly below a hundred million francs except in the crisis of 1912-1913. How was the bank able to free itself from the burden ? In the first place the Treasury was obliged to ensure an average annual payment of one hun- dred millions from the home budget, which represented in the period under consideration relief to the extent of one thousand millions. For the other five hundred millions the bank was obliged, failing credit in France, to utilize its debt in Algeria. This sum did not therefore leave the colony but represents the new capital applied to its development. This new capital has been transferred from France to Algeria by a stroke of the pen , and has been obtained by drawing on the bank which is France's chief debtor and which converts home funds into its notes. Thus the criterion according to which the Banque de I'Algerie regulates the Algerian money market is perceived, the principle namely of avoiding above all else the disproportionate growth of its debt to the Treasury. The Algerian banks are definitely neither agencies for managing de- posits nor agencies for discounting paper. The}'' depend on colonization and the amount of their business is proportionate to its progress. It is the 62 AI^GERIA - CREDIT new colonists who increase their cHentele and therefore they favour them, in fact finance them. Credit is very easity obtained in this colony. The ne- cessary means are supplied b}' the original mechanism to which we have alluded and which M. Avenol succinctly' and very accurately describes as follows : " Three large banks operate in Algeria. Two of them there employ capital obtained either locally or in France. These resources of their own give them a precious autonomy, but the course of their business is slow. Do they not perhaps limit their credit business too rigidly ? " It is the part of the Banque de I' A I gerie to give elasticit}' to the system. An issuing bank having a small capital, it finds resources in its notes pay- able to bearer : subject to no obligation as regards cover, it makes a cur- rency of the credit it affords. It has a direct clientele with whom its oper- ations are very important. But it also rediscounts the paper of banks. Its fiduciary circulation constitutes the principal mone}- of Algeria, and — varsing with the amount of business done — is always complementar}- to the capital of the banks. Thus Algeria makes advances to itself. " Unfortunately this circulation has no international value, not be- cause it is itself vicious but because Algeria is always in the position of a debtor to the mother-covmtry. "Thanks however to a curious mechanism connecting French creditors and Algerian debtors payments are made in francs at par, as though France and Algeria were one country. By an administrative device the bank is the onty debtor, the Treasury the only creditor. This disadvantageous posi- tion is exactly that which gives the bank an interest in pla^'ing that moder- ating role which is suited to an issuing bank. It is the course of its indebt- edness to the Treasury which gives it the data whence to determine the rate of discount, and the course of discount makes the suppW of capital in Algeria proportionate to sound business ". This necessity of maintaining the current account with the Treasury at a just level was made particularlj^ clear by the crisis of 1912-1913. This crisis was an indirect result of the very abundant corn harvest and vintage of 1910. The resources consequent^ available certainly gave a new im- pulse to land purchase and the bringing of land under cultivation, but the}- led more particularly to expenditure on luxuries — the value of imports increasing by 150 million francs in three years — and to speculation. X.^n- fortunately in 1912 Algerian business ceased to develop smoothly and lost equilibrium. The paper of the Banqiie de I'Algerie was increased to excess b}' rediscounting operations with other banks which found their resources largely absorbed by the need for credit. At the same time the debit bal- ance of the Banque de I'Algerie with the Treasury' rose inordinatel}' , be- cause the product of discounted bills was largely sent to France while the bills given by the bank returned to it by the medium of the post-office. Bj' opportune!}' raising its decreed rate of discount the Banque de I'Algerie put a stop to this flow of business, and the two great private banks decided to increase their capital and were thus able to re-establish equilibrium. CANADA SCHEME FOR THE ORGANIZATION OF RURAIv MORTGAGE CREDIT IN MANITOBA, SASKATCHEWAN AND AI^BERTA. SOURCE : The Grain Growers' Guide, Winnipeg, 22 November 1916. Mr. Edward Brown, provincial treasurer of Manitoba, has together with the provincial treasurers of Saskatchewan and Alberta drawn up an interesting scheme for the uniform organization of rural mortgage credit in these three provinces. It seems that the scheme will shortly be- come law. It does not exactly reproduce any of the various systems of mortgage loans followed in the different countries of the world, but has been inspired b}^ one and another of them, adopting their provisions and modifying them, where necessary, to meet the needs of West Canada. It has therefore its own individuality although it is based on the well-known principle of amor- tization. The governments of the three provinces cited propose to form in each of them a special organization to be known in Manitoba as the " Manitoba Rural Credit's Association " and to have its headquarters in Winnipeg. This association will have the duty of applying the system of mortgage credit and will be under a board of management consisting of five members. The chairman or commissioner will be the only permanent official and will be appointed by the government. Two members of the board will be nominated by the Union of Municipalities and the other two by the govern- ment. Two of the members of the board will be Conservatives and two of them Liberals. It will be provided in the legislation that money will be lent b}' the Rural Credit's Association on first mortgages on occupied farms, only for the following purposes : — i) To provide for the purchase of land for agricultural uses. 2) To provide for the purchase of the equipment, fertilizers and live stock necessary to the proper and reasonable working of a mortgaged farm. 64 CAXADA - CREDIT 3) To provide buildings and enable improvements on the land — the term " improvements " to be defined by the board. 4) To liquidate the existing debts of the owner of the mortgaged land, or debts hje subsequentlj^ incurs for the purposes which have been cited, the board at all times first approving such expenditure. Some especial provisions cf the scheme will now be given. The smallest loan that will be granted is one cf $500, the largest one of $10,000. None will exceed 50 per cent, of the value of the land as ap- praised for agricultural purposes, its earning power being principally con sidered in appraising. No persons except farmers, actuallj' engaged in farming or about to engage in it, will be able to secure loans. No borrower will be allowed to sell or transfer his share in the association, which will remain permanently attached as part of the mortgage transaction. If he sell his farm the board has power to transfer the mortgage and also the shares to the purchaser. If he die the mortgage and shares may go to his heirs. Every applicant for a loan will use a regular prescribed form on which will be stated the objects for which the loan is to be used. Penal- ties will be provided for wilful mis-statements. If any borrower .spend any part of his loan for purposes other than those specified in his appli- cation, or violate his mortgage contract in any way, the board will have power to declare his mortgage due and payable at once. All payments on the mortgages will be made on i Decem.ber, thus falling due together and so reducing the work of administering the scheme. The date is chosen as being that most convenient to farmers. It is the plan to charge 8 per cent, interest on all overdue payments. All mortgaged buildings are to be insured to the board's satisfaction. lyoans will be made only for term.s of twenty, thirty or forty years, the principal and interest to be repaid in annual instalments adjusted according to the t'^rm. Thus a $1,000 mortgage for twent}^ 3'ears will entail a repay- ment of $87.22 a year, for principal and interest, and this will discharge the entire obligation in the twenty years. On a thirty year mortgage of $1,000 the annual pajanent due will be $71.02 ; on a forty year mortgage of $1,000 it will be 63.27. The following table shows the annual payments due for a thirty year mortgage. SCHEME FOR THE ORGAN IZATIOX OF RURAL MORTGAGE CREDIT 65 Yearly Payments for a Thirty Year Mortgage under the Proposed Scheme (i). Year Principal Balance I $ I,0Ot1.0O 2 986.88 3 9^3-Oo 4 958.31 5 942.76 6 926.35 7 • • • 90S. 97 8 890.58 9 871.12 10 850.54 II 828.77 12 805.74 13 781.37 14 755-59 15 728.32 16 699.47 17 668.95 18 636.66 19 602.50 20 566.37 21 528.14 22 487-70 23 444-92 24 399-66 25 351-78 26 301-13 27 247.55 2,8 : 190.87 29 131. 10 30 67.68 Interest Principal Reserve Total 5% Repayment 0-79 % Paj-ments \ 50.00 s 13.12 % 7-90 71.02 49-34 13.88 7.80 71.02 48.65 14.69 7.68 71.02 47-92 15-53 7.57 71.02 47-14 • 16.43 7.45 71.02 46.32 17-38 7-32 71.02 45-45 18.39 7.18 71.02 44-53 19.46 7-03 71.02 43-56 20.58 6.88 71.02 42-53 21.77 6.72 71-02 41-44 23.03 6.55 71.02 40.28 24-37 6.37 71.02 39-07 25-78 6.17 7I.C2 37.78 27-27 5-97 71.02 36.42 28.S5 5-75 71.02 34-97 30-52 5-53 71.02 33-45 32.29 5-28 71.02 31-83 34-16 5-03 . 71.02 30-13 36-13 4.76 71.02 28.32 38.23 4-47 71.02 26.41 40.44 4-17 71.02 24-39 42.78 3-85 71.02 22.25 45.26 3.51 71.02 19.98 47.88 3.16 71.02 17-59 50.65 2.78 71-02 15.06 53-58 2.38 71.02 12.38 56.^ 1.96 71.02 9-54 59-77 1. 71 71.02 6.56 63.42 1.04 71.02 3-38 s 67.11 53 71.02 § 976.67 999-43 % 154-50 S 2,130.60 Ordinaril)' it would be expected that the farmers in Western Canada would not care to assume mortgages running from twenty to forty years, but the new scheme allows any farmer to pay off his mortgage in full at any half-yearly period. He will thus benefit by the low rate of interest and the small pa^-ments and yet have the opportunity of discharging his mortgage whenever he is in a position to do so. After the necessar}- provincial legislation has been enacted no money will be lent to an}' farmer until the municipality in which he resides has sub- (i) In mikiiig the calculations in even dollars and ccnls a small ditTcrence (,-,;cents) ixcurs which would be absorbed in actual practice. 66 CANADA - CREDIT niitted a by-law to the electors and their majority has voted in favour of it. The Act will then be brought into operation in this ^lunicipaHt3^ A municipality by its approval of the by-law will guarantee the government against loss on mortgages placed within it to the extent of 5 per cent, of the money lent. This measure is intended to improve the security of the bonds which will be issued, and it is not expected that there will be anj' losses. When the by-law has been approved the municipal council will ap- point a committee, either of its own members or others, to inspect farmers' applications for loans and, at their discretion, to recommend them to the board. The secretary-treasurer of the municipality will receive all apphcations for loans as part of his regular duties and without extra payment from the government, but there is nothing to prevent the municipality from arrang- ing extra payment for him for this work. The proposal of the government is to raise the necessarj'^ mone}'' by offering 5 per cent, bonds, on which both principal and interest will be guar- anteed by the government, for sale throughout the province and in the money markets of the world. It is expected that they will sell at par at the present time and that the necessary money will therefore cost the government about 5 per cent. The expense of administering the Act is expected to be not quite i per cent., so that the total average cost of mort- gages will be less than 6 per cent, on thirty j^ear loans. The government intends the Rural Credits Association never to be commercialized. Tn future years all its capital stock and shares are to be held by the government, or farmers who have borrowed from it on mort gages, and who will have received 5 per cent, of their loans in shares. The shares are expected to pay a fairly good dividend, depending en- tirely on the profits of the association. No dividends will be paid until a reserve account, equal to 20 per cent, of the paid-up capital, has been created. The profit in the conduct of the association is expected to come through the cheapness of administration, and the margin which is provided by the fact that the rate of interest on repayments is lower than that on the orig- inal loan. To set the .scheme in operation in Manitoba the government will ar- range to borrow from the banks at 5 per cent, the sum of $1,000,000 dol- lars, and to subscribe for -Sioo.ooo stock in the association. When the $1,000,000 has been lent on mortgages 5 per cent, of this sum, or $50,000, will have been subscribed in stock by borrowers. The government will then issue guaranteed 5 per cent, bonds, free from all local taxation, to the maximum extent of $9,000,000. To keep down the cost of administration the government will pro\'ide that the Land Titles Office make no charge for investigating titles and re- gistering mortgages, placed by the Rural Credit's Association, bej^ond the regular registration fees. The government in Manitoba will also provide SCHEME FOR THE ORGANIZATION OF RURAL, MORTGAGE CREDIT 67 that the accounting work in connection with the mortgages be done in the office of the comptroller general, without charge to the association. The rate at which farm mortgages will be secured will involve a saving of from I to 2 14 V^^ cent, in Manitoba and from 2 to 4 per cent, in Saskat- chewan and Alberta. The scheme may have become actual next spring. If it prove satisfac- tory the governments of the provinces concerned are expected, in the course of a year or two, to tackle the question of what is commonly known as " float- ing credit for farmers ", the loans which carry them over from seed-time to harvest. These now cost from 8 to 12 per cent, and it is hoped that it will be possible to supply them more cheaply. MISCEl^LANEOUvS INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. ARGENTINE RF.PUBLIC. THE FRANCO-ARGENTINE MORTGAGE BANK IN i'jis-iqi6. — U information, Paris, 27 December igi6. The results obtained in 1915-1916 have again been injuriously influen- ced by the stagnation of business, which has continued in the Argentine, contrary to the hopes raised by an excellent corn harvest and b}^ the great need in Europe for the country's products. The profits which the farmers hoped to reap from abundant harv^ests and the high selling prices in purchasing countries were sensiblj^ reduced by the great difficulty of finding ships for transport and the consequent enormous rise in freights, which in many cases, and notabty in those of corn and maize, came to surpass the value of the merchandize in the produc- ing country. Hence in the Argentine the price of cereals sank to a level which left hardly any profit to agriculture ; exportation was arrested ; and landowners were in consequence much embarassed. The mortgage banks naturally felt the reaction from this economic situation ; and the Franco- Argentine Bank found, in spite of its caution in granting loans and its vigilance in exacting due annual payments, that the arrears of interest owing to it amounted on 30 June 1916 to 11,836,777.90 francs. In consequence however of the slowing down of business, of the reduc- tion of the habitual expenditure of the republic in foreign countries, and the reduction of imports, the unemploj^ed capital in the banks is very plen- tiful and can be obtained on easy terms. Therefore, in spite of the straits of landowners, mortgage banks have been obHged to lower the rate of in- terest on their loans. But, since the cereal harvest in North America and Europe was defective, prices have risen in the Argentine, and for some time an improvement in the economic situation has been perceptible. INFORMATIOX RELATIXG TO CREDIT 69 Bonds. — The bonds, redeemed bonds being deducted, amounted on 30 June 1916 to 187433 at 4 per cent, 242,458 at 4.50 per cent. 49,511 at 5 per cent. that is a total of 479,402 bonds representing a nominal capital of 238,701,000 francs. Mortgage Looms. — On 30 June 1915 the amoimt of mortgage loans reached 247,751,622 francs. During the year T915-1916 the society examined loi apphcations for loans, for a total amount of 41,165,000 francs. Fifty of them, repre- senting 13,137,000 francs, were rejected, and the society therefore granted only fifty-one new loans for a total amount of 28,028,000 francs, of which sum 26,848,000 francs have already been paid. On the other hand the society recovered during the 3'ear 39,843,072 francs, by repayments of mature loans, anticipation of repayments and expropriations. The amount of current mortgage loans diminished by 12,995,072 francs, their total siun being 234,756,550 francs on 30 June 1916. This sum was made up as follows : Urban loans 16,290,950 francs Rural » 218,465,600 )> 234756,550 The rural loans thus represent 93.06 per cent, of the total amount of current loans. Payment of Annuities. — The amount of the annuities falling due on 30 June 1915 and not paid on that date was 10,377,879.20 francs. The half-yearly payments which fell due during the year amounted to 20,299,133.70 francs. The total sum of yearly pa^anents to be received between i Jul}' 1915 and 30 June 1916 was therefore 30,677,012.90 francs. Of this sum 18,840,235 francs was recovered, so that on 30 June 1916 the am.ount of due and unpaid annual payments was 11,836.777.90 francs. Most of the debtors show excellent dispositions ; but the situation in which the last few years has placed them makes it difficult for such of them as were not at first able to meet their engagements to free themselves now. It is therefore returns arising out of earlier ^-ears which are most easily col- lected. 70 INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT FRENCH COLONIES. THE DISCOUNT AND I,OAN TRANSACTIONS OF COI^ONIAl, BANKS. — Ordinary ses- sion of Chamber of Deputies, meeting of i8 December 1916 Appendix no. 2793. Report in the name of the Commission for Foreign Affairs, the Protectorates and the Colonies, charged to examine a proposed law for the prorogation of the prv'ilege of colonial banks and of their by- laws . , The discount and loan transactions of the colonial banks have not at any moment been interrupted ; and in spite of the state of war the figure representing these, by far the most interesting of banking transactions from the point of view of economic activity, shows a very noticeable ad- vance on similar figures for previous 3'ears. Martinique. — Thus the Bank of Martinique did not hesitate to give an exceptional importance to its loans on harvests which rose to the sum of 4,528,000 francs (i) as against 3,595,000 francs in 1913-1914 ; that is they increased by nearly a milHon. In the same wa}^ the loans on merchan- dise passed from 676,000 francs, their sum in 1913-1914, to 1,169,000 francs in 1914-1915 and 1,764,000 francs in 1915-1916 ; that is the transac- tions of this one kind increased in value by 1,100,000 francs in two years. The total amount of the loan and discount transactions of the Bank of Martinique, including tiie negotiation of bills in foreign countries, rose from 23,164,000 francs in 1913-1914 to 34,485,000 francs in 1914-1915 and 37,124,000 francs in 1915-1916 ; that is the increase in two years was one of fourteen millions or 66 per cent. Guadeloupe. — The same considerations and statements are appli- cable to the Bank of Guadeloupe, the advances of which have been in a very large proportion, as in Martinique, in the form of loans on harvests. This bank in 1914-1915 made such advances to the amount of 4,176,400 francs as against 3,576,000 francs in 1913-1914. It is to be noted that the loans on harvests, although the^^ involve such large risks, have been made at a rate no higher than loans by the Bank of France on fir.st -class French securities, namely 6 per cent. In other words the Bank of Guadeloupe, which might most legitimately have raised this very low rate, has subordinated all considerations of private interest to care for the public interest. As in ]\lartinique loans on merchandise have been notably developed during the war. Their total rose from 114,530 francs in 1913-1914 to 420,500 francs in 1914-1915 and 805,950 francs in 1915-1916. The total sum of the discount and loan transactions of the Bank of Guadeloupe, including the negotiation of bills in foreign countries, was 27,879,670 francs in 1914-1915 and 31,510,440 francs in iqi5-i9i6 as against 22,767,800 francs in 1913-1914. (i) I franc = g 3/g d at \va\. INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT 71 Reunion. — The Bank of Reunion has evinced since the very begin- ning of the war a remarkable spirit of initiative, taking steps without wait- ing for an}' sort of impulsion, whatever might be the gravity of the risks involved. In the first place this bank notified the governor of the colony as early as I August 191.-J, that is before war had been declared, that it would meet any needs which might arise if the colon}^ shoirld be isolated by the inter- ruption of communications with Paris. This undertaking had reference not only to the needs of manufacturers, planters and cultivators of every description, but also to those of the colon}', even if it should com.e to be deprived of an important part of its receipts b}'' the anticipated reduction in the revenue from customs dues and tolls. The bank offered these ser- vices to the colony spontaneously and thus gave proof of its desire not to allow the general interest to suffer. Subsequentl}', when it had advertised in all the newspapers of the colom^ that it would continue to work as in the past, it decided to grant advances on nierchandise at the rate of 6 per cent. — a rate less bj' i per cent, than that on which the Bank of France then made advances on the best security — to all large and small planters, manufacturers and business men of every description. This rate, low as it was in the existing circums- tances, has been yet further reduced since November 1Q15 to 5 per cent, for loans on merchandise for export and on most imported wares, notably rice, that is on almost all merchandise. The bank has done even better in the matter of loans on harvests, which are one of the most risky of banking transactions and are effected onl}^ by the banks of the old colonies. In their case it has maintained the 5 per cent, rate which is so favourable to local agriculture, and is less by I per cent, than that now charged by the Bank of France on the safest tran- sactions. Further, since it reasonabl}^ anticipated from the time of the outbreak of hostilities a verj- considerable rise in the price of sugar, the principal ar- ticle of export, it recommended ^all producers, whether large or small, not to sell at the prices current when the war began. It advised small produc- ers to form themselves into groups in order to receive the loan which it would grant them on pledged goods, and to incur responsibility in the name of one of their number, thus avoiding the payment of registration and stamp- ing dues (three francs a deed). Finally, since the bank believed that the exploitation of persons of small means by speculators must be avoided at all costs, it refused to make certain advances on pledges which would have had a purely speculative character; and shorth' afterwards organized at its own cost a service of information by cable, thus apprising the popula- tion of the prices which the different colonial products were fetching in Paris. The loans which the bank granted on the products of the colony in these conditions rose from 5,915,000 francs in 1913-1914 to 10,072,600 francs in 1914-1915, that is to say thej- were doubled. Between 1913-1914 and T915-1916 the loans on imported merchandise rose from 3,555.000 7^ INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT francs to 6.268,000 francs ; and the total sum of loans on merchandise, both imported and exported, from 9,471.000 francs to 15,502,000 francs. As regards the total sum of loan and discount transactions, including the negotiation of bills pn foreign countries, it passed from 21,082,290 francs in 1913-1914 to 39,795,400 francs in 1915-1916. French Guiana. - In Guiana the privileged bank which, owing to the special economic situation of the colony, transacts business differenth/ from the other colonial banks, has also very definitely faced existing cir- cumstances only from the point of view of the public interest, a fact which is sufficiently proved by the annual report drawn up by the governor of the colonj^ on the general situation of Guiana, and reproduced in the Jour- nal Officiel of the republic of 15 October 1915. We will quote from this document only the following short extract : " The bank then decided to make advances to the producers on their products of which there had thus come to be a slump, and to enable them to continue work by ensuring the wages of the workpeople. " It should be realized that the bank made these advances on raw products at the discount rate of 6 per cent, a year, which for the four months which were the average term of the transactions, yielded a profit of 2 per cent. " This rate should be considered very low for Guiana, where money costs as much as 20 per cent. It would have been moderate even in France where the rate of discount has latterly risen to as much as 9 per cent. " It should also be remembered that the goods pledged to the bank had only a conventional value, that no one could foresee when it would be possible to realize the value of these products which were security'' for the loans. " It may be said that in undertaking these transactions, as in tak- ing other opportune steps, the bank has been led above all b}- a broad interpretation of its duty as a privileged establishment. " .... The bank took the point of view of the colon^^'s highest and most general interest. Far from taking restrictive measures it enlarged the scope of its transactions. It placed no obstacle in t-he way of the with- drawal of deposited funds ; it provided the resources necessary for the con- tinuation of industry ; it maintained its low rate of discount and reduced the premium of its tirages in spite of the increased cost of exchange trans- actions ". It appears from the reports of the Bank of Guiana that the figure representing its loans on merchandise rose in 1914-1915 to 1,039,000 francs as against 192,700 francs in 1913-1914 ; that is to say that the importance of these transactions was ra.ultiplied by six. As regards the total sum of the bank's transactions it reached 9,233,350 francs in 1913-1914, 9,995,310 francs in 1914-1915, and 12,402,830 francs in 1915-1916. Generally, credit has been granted by the banks of the old colonies since the outbreak of hostilities on terms which are noticeably better than those prevalent in France. Yet rates much higher than those obtaining in Europe have always, notoriously, been considered normal in the colonies. INFORMATION RElvATING TO CREDIT 73 RUSSIA. THE QUESTION OF FOREST CREDIT IN FINLAND. — VESTERINEN (Emil) : Ky- symys lainan antamisesta metsdvakimtta vastaan (The Question of Credit on the Security of Forest Mortgages), Maatalous, Helsingfors, Year iear arms but only in return for the payment of this tax. The male ^lusulman population was called to arms three times at dif- ferent periods. In the case of each summons the tax payable for military exemption corresponded to 50 Turkish pounds (i). As regards the non-Ma- hometan population the tax fell on groups of persons in a single locality and not on individuals. Each group of a hundred males of a given villa ge had to pay 50 Turkish pounds, which sum was afterwards divided among the indi\'iduals composing such a gfoup in accordance with the wealth each possessed. Priests and males under fifteen or over sevent^'-five years old were exempt from all military taxes. § 2. Agrarian taxes after the occupation nr Austria AND HUNGARY. The Austrian and Hungarian government, immediateh* after the occu- pation of Bosnia and Herzegovina, proposed to solve the agrarian proljlem as well as possible, and placed therefore at the head of an economic pro- gramme the reform of taxation and the redemption of the land in the interests of the kineti. With this aim the opportune work of forming a cadaster was undertak- en without delay ; but the nomination of Kalaj as governor of Austria and Hungary caused both the schemes for the reform of taxation and the solu- tion of the problems relative to the redemption of land from ancient feu- dal bonds to be shelved, because they were contrary to the principles on which the new governor's economic policy was founded. The fundamental basis of this policj- was the maintenance at all costs of internal peace, in homage to which principle Kalaj renounced all projects of reform, however necessary they might be to the country's economic pro- gress. He feared that he might come up against ancient cu.stoins, disturb local interests, and thus occasion internal disorder, and he was convinced that taxation could not be reformed without arousing discontent among the whole population : thus during the time of his administration he adher- ed to Canard's theory- that any tax in existence in a given country is good for the sole reason that it has become intermixed with local customs and the local relations connecting the interests of individuals ; and therefore that an}' new tax is — as a matter of logical sequence — bad because of the sole fact of its novelty. Accepting this theorj' as a maxim Kalaj did not nevertheless absolutely renounce all reformation but had recourse to half measures which could not produce anj^ really noteworthy advantage. He excluded all that could represent a truly radical reform of ta:fation and con- tented himself with retouches which did little to relieve the ancient system in force in the country. (i) Turkish pound = 18.22725 at par. AGRARIAN' TAXES IX BOSXIA AXD HERZEGOVIXA 8 1 During his tenure of office, which lasted for more than twenty years, he introduced in fact onh- the following changes into the sj-stem of taxation inherited from the Turkish government : i) For the payment of the tithe in kind a payment in cash was sub- stituted. The basis on which this was effected was the market price of the various articles of merchandise representing the tax in kind, and the quantity- of these produced on a given holding. 2) For the collection of the tithe b}' the medium of responsible col- lectors, as described, the s^'stem of direct collection by the vState was substi- tuted. 3) The tithes still payable to Vacouf properties were made payable to the State. This was effected gradually. At the time of the Austrian and Hxingarian occupation these entities so privileged still existed, although their number was small, and until igii they are mentioned in official re- ports. It should be noted that all the retouching of the old Turkish s^'stem of taxation eff'ected under Kalaj's administration was profitable onl}^ to the agas, to whom the kmeti were by old feudal bonds obliged to give a part of the products of the soil they cultivated, that is a tribute in kind, called Hac in the language of the country. When Kalaj had introduced his reform it fell to the governor's agents to fix for each holding the quantity of its produce and the share of this which belonged to the State as a tax. This calculation, which had an official source and therefore was not much subject to error, afterwards served the agas as a sure basis for establishing the amount of the products of the soil due to themselves from their re- spective kmeti. The latter, as has been said, derived no advantage from the reform of taxation in question. After the death of Kalaj his successor Barian devoted himself to the task of reforming taxation. He took for point of departure the reform of the tithe, which was considered to be the worst of all the forms of taxa- tion. At first he thought of substituting for it a tax on revenue, but fearing that too rapid a transition from one system of taxation to another might arouse discontent and disorder in the country he prefererd a provi- sionar}^ measury, the introduction namely of the so-called tithe in the block. This is the name given to the following system : In the case of ever}' single piece of land to be taxed its average gross product in the period between 1895 and 1905 was ascertained. Such aver- age was multiplied by the average price of a unit of the various products ; and thus a figure was obtained the tenth part of which represented the tax due to the State and payable in money. For motives of prudence this new system of taxation was introduced in 1905 only in two or three villages of each department. The result obtained was so satisfactory that in the next year — 1906 — the law was passed in virtue of which the system of the tithe in the block was adopted as the offi- cial system of taxation applicable to the whole country except the districts which still lacked a cadaster. This reform met with favour above all from tlie kmeti because the dif- AUSTRIA AND HUNGARY - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL f erence between the quantity of products which they obtained from their respective cultivated holdings, and the quantity of such products officially certified by the agents of the State, remained exempt from any tax to the Treasur}^ and any feudal contribution to the agas, Among the different secondary reforms adopted, other than that of the tithe in the block, we note the following : i) The perpetual exemption from every tax on their products of vegetable and other gardens near dwelling-houses, if they have an area of no more than a dunum (i). 2) The temporary exemption for ten years of lands recenth' brought under cultivation. 3) The temporary exemption from taxation of lands granted to colo- nists, whether these belong to the population of the country or be of foreign nationality. 4) Partial or total exemption from the tithe in bad years. 5) The total exemption from taxation of the products of vegetable and other gardens cultivated by soldiers or fiscal agents, provided such products be not intended for sale. 6) The total exemption from taxation of lands of the State cultiva- ted with a view to their improvement. It may be stated more precisel}^ that the system of taxation here de- scribed is applied, with the exceptions previously indicated, to products of all arable lands and to those of apiaries. As regards woodlands these also are burdened w^ith the tithe in the block, calculated on their net return based on the data in the cadaster. The reform of taxation which we have described was initiated in 1905 and terminated in 1907. Its application was prorogued only in the four de- partments of Biletch, Bazco, Ljubinje and Trebinje because all these lacked a cadaster. The expenses relative to the reform of taxation amounted to 1,600,000 crowns (2) As regards the expenses of collection these were by the new system diminished by 70 per cent, in comparison with those in- volved by other methods of collecting taxes. The old Suliis and Verghia taxes, to wdiich we have already alluded and the abolition of which was begun while Turkish domination was still in force, were little by little replaced by taxes on returns. In fact in the official report for 1911 these taxes are mentioned only in relation to the five depart- ments of Zepzc, Gasko,Foca, Ljubinje and Trebinje, while in all the others the new taxes on laud, buildings, moveables and the returns from labour had alrespcly been applied in this period. The new land tax was planned as an improvement to be introduced into the system of collection represented by the tithe. It should be regarded as the beginning of the reform of taxation in Bosnia and Herzegovina, a reform which aims at causing the incidence of taxes on proprietors and not on cultivators and at making the real value of the land the basis of taxa- (1)1 dunum = about 1091 I/2 square yards. (2) I crown of gold = 10.0809 d at par. AGRARIAN TAXES IN BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA 83 tiop. The tax in question is one of 4 per thousand In the district of Banja- Luka it is calculated on the net return of the land as given b\^ the cadaster and it is there 3.6 per cent. The tax on buildings has the same characteristic features as that on land. Like the latter it falls only on the aga proprietors while the kmeii are exempt from it. Buildings newly erected are not taxed for a period of from five to ten years. The basis of the tax in question is the estimated value of the buildings. Since all such estimates made in the time of the Turkish government are entirely inexact, recourse was had to a commission charged to rectify errors in calculation and to establish a new and more accurate general estimate of the property in question, and at the same time to make a cadaster. This tax is one of 4 per thousand of the estimated real value of taxable buildings, or — if they be let — of 4 per cent, of their rent. As regards the tax on live stock it may be said to be the same as under the Turkish government. It falls only on sheep, goats and pigs ; cattle and horses being exempt from it. Its amount has however been modified with the intention of promoting the rearing of sheep and diminishing that of goats. The amount is as follows : For every sheep in a flock 20 hellers (i) are paid, but for each person liable to pay the tax ten sheep are exempt from it, as are all lambs. Where goats are concerned the tax varies, with districts and with the number of the goats, from 40 hellers to a crown. Moreover the tax is progressive : for the first ten goats it is 40 hellers, for the second ten 45 hellers, and so on. This rate is not applied in Herzegovina. For kids under a year old no tax is paid. Pigs are taxed at the rate of 60 hellers each. The tax on live stock is in general paid in three instalments, in March, April and May. The amounts of the various taxes examined are indicated in the follow- ing table which has reference to igio : Total value of tithe 8,853,000 the taxes SiUits and Verghia 69,800 tax on land 847,300 " buildings 1,028,900 sheep and goats 779,800 pigs 67,000 11,645,800 A part of the total value of all the taxes, seen by this table to b e 11,645,800 crowns, falls only on the agricultural population, nam.ely (i) 10 hellers = about id at par. 54 AUSTRIA AND Hl'XGARY - AORICl I.'i L'KAL l■,CO^'u:\l^: lA GENERAL 10.543,100 crowns, which sum comprises the tithe, the land tax and the tax on live stock. The remainder, namely the sum of the tax on buildings and the Snlus and Verghia taxes, falls both on the agricultural and the urban populations. Both also pa}- indirect taxes. It is very difficult to determine in what proportion these two classes of the population of Bosnia and Herzegovina contribute respective!}" to the payment of indirect taxes. Only an approxi- mate calculation can be made, based on statistical data relative to the total sum of the indirect taxes levied in 1910. The following table results : Taxes on tobacco 17,429,000 Dues and registration 4,063,835 Taxes on sugar 3. 977-^17 " salt 3,259,900 spirits 2,647,207 mineral oils 809,555 " " beer 569,688 gunpowder 33-451 As appears from these statistical data, indirect taxes in Bosnia and Her- zegovina fall on articles of general consumption, nameh- such as are consum- ed as much by the rich as by the poor population, some of them — like salt and spirits — more by the poor than by the rich. We may therefore conclude with the statement that the agricultural population of Bosnia and Herzegovina is burdened with indirect taxes in proportion to its numbers. The taxed portion of the population may, according to the last census, that of 1910, be stated to constitute 86.57 P^^ cent, of the whole. The statistical table which follows .shows the movement of indirect taxation from 1881-82 and through the succeeding quinquennial periods until 1910 : AGRARIAN TAXES IX BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINA 8s 31-82 1895 1910 Tithe Sulus, Verghia Taxes on landb .... c » buildings (i) . .. » » (2) . )i » sheep & goats. » pigs I- 1) tobacco . . . Various taxes Taxes on susar .... » salt >' » spirits. . . . " » mineral oils . » » beer » i> ganpowder . . 4,854,000 323,100 586,400 219,100 59.300 442,200 7;,900 3,500,900 716,188 52,000 13.130 5,925,000 356,600 465,000 215,000 68,300 708,200 102,500 4,746,000 1,268,124 22,962 30,651 8,113,000 357,700 479,200 273,600 86,600 691,100 121,700 8,512,000 1,349-899 2,146,000 696,000 74,772 39,373 8,404,000 69,700 700,400! 429,900 124,300 892,300 140,800 9.533.000 1,582,691 345,994 2,264,000 1,234,000 610,904 216,876 24.329 7.733,000 69,200 719,500 578,400 149,100 811,300 95,400 10,027,000 1.923.113 1,696,759 2,639,000 1,603,000 575.146 282,000 37.511 8,976,000 69,400 759,300 603,500 227,200 820,000 86,100 12,278,000 2,381,707 2,765,000 2,899,000 1,609,000 471,000 395.000 33,151 8,853,000 69,300 847,300 739,200 286,700 779,800 67,000 17,429,000 4.063,835 3.977.017 3,259,900 2,647,207 809,555 569.685 33.451 (i) Taxes on tlie value of buildings. (2) Taxes on the rent of buildings. GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND. AGRICULTURE AND THE WAR. SOURCE : The Journal of the Board of Agriculture, Vol. XXIII. Number 8, I^ondon, No- vember 1916. At Taunton on the 28th of last October the members of the Somerset War Agricultural Committee and others were addressed by Lord Crawford, then President of the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries. Lord Crawford first alluded to the difficulties at present attendant on agriculture, those connected with labour and tillage, with the late harvest which meant a late autumn, and above all with the feeling of uncertainty which hung over agriculture. It was the object, not only of farmers but also of the whole country in relation to agriculture, to obtain more food. Ten 3'ears ago agriculture had been looked upon by the country at large as an industry ; now it was recognized to a be source and foundation of national strength. Ten years ago agriculture had been merely a commercial occupation, and not always a very brilliant one ; now it was one of the weapons bj' which Britain meant to win the great war. To realize the want for more food was almost a discovery to the British public. Hitherto food had reached the country somehow and from somewhere — it had not been the business of the consumer to enquire how, when or whence it came. Too often he had closed his eyes to those who pointed out the danger of allowing agriculture to be neglected and to decay. Now he was beginning to find not only that more food was needed, but also that the source and origin of that food was one of its essential values when it was required by the consumer. Every quarter of corn that was imported weakened the countr}^ and every quarter grown at home conferred strength on the country. If corn were bought abroad it was paid for abroad. During the war the one transaction of all others which it was desirable to avoid was that of sending money abroad to ])urchase articles which could be produced at home. Such a course weakened the British exchange, diminished British financial resources ; AGRICULTURE AND THE WAR 87 and the financial resources of the country were one of the great weapons with which Britain was fighting the war. To buy corn abroad was, further, to make a call upon the mercantile marine which could be used for more pro- fitable transactions; and it was to requisition fresh labour after the corn had been imported, for unloading at the docks, reloading into trains and distribution. Thus the importation of corn stuffs during the war was not a strength but a weakness to the whole country. Wheat. — The country depended on two fundamental foodstuffs — wheat and meat — and the last harvest had shown a serious decrease in the area of wheat as compared with 1915. Last summer, in England and Wales alone, the area under wheat which had been harvested had been less by more than a quarter of a million acres than in 1915, and the average yield over the reduced acreage would probably prove to have been considerably less than in that A^ear (i). It was essential, with a view to the prospects for next summer, that the maximum area should be planted with wheat in the coming months. Although it was probabb; impossible to match the high results of 1915, what could be done should and must be done. To plant wheat would paj- the farmer, for prices would be remunerative next August even if peace w^ere declared at Easter, and it would pay the country. It should be remembered that the only basis on which the Board of Agriculture could press for the retention on the land of all possible labour, was that the labour now avail- able was being used to the utmost in the national interest, regardless of whether the ultimate profit were going to be large or small. Live Stock. — In Somerset the work started by the Board of Agricul- ture in connection with the Eive Stock Improvement vScheme had been taken up as successfully as in any county in England, if not more so. The first grant imder the scheme was made onlj" six months before the war broke out, yet Somerset was now earning the maximum grant which the Board was entitled to pay, namely £1,000 a year. The live stock societies in the county owned seventeen subsidized boars, averaging £7. 6 s. in value a piece, and thirty-four bulls averaging over £40 in value a piece, and their record as to Shire horses was good. The improve- ment effected by the Live Stock Scheme was illustrated by the fact that these bulls replaced others, existing before the scheme, of which the average value certainly did not reach £25. The first milk recording societ}^ under the Board's scheme was established at Cadbury in April 19 14 and its members and others had realized that a milk recording certificate had a definite commercial value. There were two other milk recording societies in the count}' ; and all three had — in spite of shortage of milkers and other war difficulties — made satisfactory' progress. (i) The preliminary statement issued by the Board of Agriculture on i November 1916 showed the total production ot wheat in England and M'^ales in 1916 to have been of 6,942,559 qurs. — that is less by 1,500,000 qurs. than in 191 s but more than in 191 2 or'1913. 88 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL This improvement in the matter of Hve stock had not only a local importance, for live stock was going to present one of the great problems of the future. It was not yet sufficiently realized in the country how much more, as time went on, Britain would have to'depend on her own re- sources. A very short time ago the United States of America had been an enormous exporting countr3\ Per head of the population it was the big- gest meat-eating country in the world. Great Britain was the third great- est meat-eating country in the world and the largest in J^urope ; her require- ments, already gigantic, showed every sign of increasing ; and while that process was going on great exporting countries like the United States of America were finding it more and more necessary to reserv'e their meat for their home populations. Therefore although new markets would naturally tend to develop elsewhere — in America or Africa, for instance — fresh de- mands would be made upon the stock owners and stock breeders at home. There had too been the ravages of war — the flocks and herds in certain parts of Europe had been devastated (Germans- herself had, since the war had begun, lost a nfilUon head of stock). The obligation upon the nation to use every means at their disposal to supplement and to maintain their flocks and herds was plain. On 5 June 1916 the annual records had been compiled by the Board of Agriculture. There were then in England and Wales a larger number of head of cattle than at any recorded date. So strong an economic position after two 3^ears of war was astonishing. In the succeeding four months the figure had probably been lowered ; yet during war time, and in view of the • extraordinary figures discovered on 5 June, the country was entitled to some extent to draw upon its capital. It was greatly to be hoped however that, although war pressure would drive in that direction, agriculturists would not yield to the ready temptation of high prices and diminish or disperse their herds. A good herd was now a good asset but it would twelve months after the declaration of peace be a still greater and more pre- cious asset. Ever}^ head of cattle which could be maintained over the war was strengthening the countrj^ as a reserve during the war, and would great- ly add to the strength of the country and its power of recuperation after the war. Wheat, live stock and crops depended however, alike, on adequate la- bour. The speaker stated that there was plenty of evidence of the inad- equacy of labour to maintain the normal standard of cultivation. Labour Shortage. — The official returns of 5 June 1916, already men- tioned, showed an increase of 112,000 acres in the land lying in bare fallow this year, as compared with the previous year. The speaker was in no doubt that this increase was due to labour shortage ; and bad labour shortage meant bad ciiltivation, bad cultivation meant poor 3'ields and meant dirty land, which meant that two or three or even four years would have to pass before the qualities of the soil could be fully restored. The army said that it wanted more men, the nation that it wanted more food, the farmer that he wanted more labour : yet we were not asked to reconcile the irrenconciliable. AGRICULTURE AXD THE WAR 89 Wcif Office Circular, 4 October 1916. ~ In the circular sent out by the Army Council on 4 October igi6 it had been decided that, subject to certain conditions, "no more men from amongst those now employed in agriculture will until January ist, 1917, and in the case of men whose whole time employment on a holding is necessary for maintaining milk pro- duction, till the 1st of April 1917, be called to the colours, except in return for men released from the colours for work in agriculture ". This was so much gained, and so much time in hand wliich was valuable time for hus- bandry. For every acre of wheat sown in the spring in the country as a whole, fifteen acres were sown in the winter. The ploughman was indeed as necessary after as before i January, but wherever it could be shown that he was necessary and within the scale for the cultivation of the land the Board was anxious that he should be retained. War Office Census. — The War Office was going to take a census of male and female workers employed on agricultural holdings ; and the returns were to be received about 15 November. The object was to enable the military authorities to survey the whole position of agricultural labour and ascertain whether the available labour were sufficient, excessive or defi- cient. It was the speaker's impression that the census would show that not only were few men emplo3'ed over the so-called I^abour Scale but that also in many districts the number of men employed was well below that scale. It was not and never had been a fixed, rigid rule. It was intended to serve as a general guide to the authorities, not necessarily • versed in agriculture at all, as to what labour should be property left upon the farms in order to ensure a reasonable scale of cultivation. The Labour Scale. — A question had been asked as to whether the La- bour Scale were permanent. Nothing in time of war could be said to be permanent, but the Labour Scale would not be altered unless the military situation demanded its alteration. Its terms were set out in full in the circular lately issued by the War Office on the subject. In the official book on registration and recruiting issued by the War Office to their officers the Labour Scale was also set out, and was preceded by this announcement : The necessity of ]?rocuring food, if possible in excess of the usual production, should be appreciated by all recruiting officers and military representatives ". Elsewhere it was said : " The military representatives are specially enjoined to watch the Hst of certified occupations, and to carry out the spirit of the instructions laid down by the various departments con- cerned ". In the same way the Local Government Board had said in their recent communication to the tribunals: " Particular attention should be paid to the official list of certified occupations, which states the classes or bodies of men engaged in agriculture whose work has been certified after consultation with the Army Council as being of national importance ". The Labour Scale was a rough and ready guide but it represented the minimum amount of labour necessary- for proper husbandry in time of war. The War Office could not give i guarantee that the Labour Scale would be maintain- ed intact, but the quotations from their own circulars showed that, they understood how necessary the Labour Scale of employment on that stan- go GREAT BRITAIN AND IREI ') :■' )) » 2nd. » Total . Liras 5.000 5,000 10,000 20,000 Expenditure. i) Travelling expenses , 2) Maintenance for two years . . . 3) Advances for crops of ist. year. 4) » )) » » 2nd. » Total 1,500 6,000 2,666 4,979 15,145 Balance- Sheet. Receipts 20,000 Expenditure I5,i45 4,855 ■ Even if the contract be cancelled at the end of the second year there were will thus be a margin almost sufficient to allow the entire repayment of the initial deposit. We will now see on what system colonists might be allowed occupation. The measures now in force do not contemplate the concession of lands in absolute ownership. The matter is regulated by article 15 of the Regola- mento per la niessa in valore delle terre nella Somalia italiana (Rules for the Development of the I,ands of Italian Somaliland) which establishes that concessions may be for a term up to ninety-nine years. In view however of the mentality of the peasants to be affected by the contract it would perhaps be very useful, and would increase the attractiveness of the scheme, to promulgate as soon as possible a royal decree which would enable the governor to sell the domain under conditions fixed bv the contract. 112 ITALIAN SOMAWLAND - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL The government advanced about 25,000 liras for the first costs of set- tlement, which sum had become 27,040 liras at the end of the first j^ear by the accumulation of interest. The annual balance sheet of crops gave at the end of the second year, as has been seen, a balance of 5,030 liras, and if 3,000 liras be deducted from this as the costs of subsistence and maintenance a net profit of 2,030 liras remains. Admitting that the initial capital of 27,040 liras at the end of the second year should be amortized in 25 3^ears, the corresponding annual instalment due would be 1,730.56 liras — a sum within the balance quoted. On this system, and on the basis of the revenue of the holding calcula- ted according to the criteria we have explained, the economic position of the holding would be such as to give the colonist the purchasing power ne- cessary to allow him to become a proprietor. An annual sum of about 300 liras would remain to his credit, and this added to the existing 3,000 liras would bring the family budget up to 3,300 liras. In order however better to ensure the success of the experiment, and to make it still more attractive, the governent might cede to the colonists a third or more of the sum represented by the capital of initial settlement. Thus the sum which the colonist would have to repay in order to become owner of the property could be reduced, for instance, to 18,000 liras or even less, according to the calculations we have shown. With a view to such a measure an offer could be made to the colonist at the end of the experiment, that is to say after three years if the experiment had given good results — of the ownership of the property burdened with an annual due from which he could free it by paying 4 per cent, on 18,000 liras — that is 720 liras. The case which we have reported would still be the basis of this plan. If it were executed the following cases might present themselves, and they should be considered before an idea of the charges which the govern- ment may have to support can be obtained. a) is^ hypothesis. — The enterprise entirely fails to reach its end in the first year. The administration is therefore in the position of having ad- vanced about 25,000 liras as costs of installation, and 7,166 liras as travelling expenses, one year's maintenance expenses and the costs of working the property ; and yet it does not consider seizing the colonist's initial deposit in order to compensate for such losses. This h3q:)othesis of a catastrophe, which is most improbable, since it is allowable to suppose that the installa- tion would not constitute a complete loss, would entail an expense of 32,166 liras. b) 2nd hypothesis — The enterprise fails only after the second or third year. In view of the government's constant superintendence and the annulment clauses in the contract li would be difficult to reach a worse result than that indicated under a). c) yd hypothesis. — The experiment succeeds so that the holding be- comes the proi:)erty of the colonist or whoever takes his place. This case should be considered in two aspects : I. The favourable result is due to the special conditions created in the colonist's favour, in that the government ma}' be said to have given him LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION II3 10,000 liras. This amounts to a failure of the experiment and should lead to an abandonment of the method. 2. The favourable result is due — as regards data and actual fact — to the productive power of the holding, and to a return from the labour of the colonist's family sufficient to allow of their permanent settlement on the holding or to call for another family to replace them. Such is the ideal end of the experiment. If it be attained, even if the specially privileged conditions enjoj^ed bj- the first colonists' families be overlooked, the ac- counts will give an exact idea of the holding's economic strength and of the organization necessary to prosperous colonization in small holdings by a white population. The most favourable h3'pothesis would presume an expenditure on the experiment bj' the government of from 10,000 to 12,000 liras, that is to say of the dift'erence between the costs of installation and the sum repaid by the colonist. • It will now be well to resume a scheme for colonization in Somaliland by the means of small proprietors, drawn up at the request of the govern- ment of Somaliland bj^ Professor Bizzozero, director of the peripatetic chair of agriculture of Parma. This scheme is important because article 37 of the Regolamento per la inessa in valore delle terre nella Somalia italiana refers to it and has largely incorporated it. We have already dealt with article 37 in speaking of the land system in Somaliland (§ 3. B.) This attempt at colonization should be begun by a limited number of cultivators' families, some twenty at most, who so soon as they reached the colony would in the presence of the governor form a first agricultural union for the colonization of Italian vSomaliland. Only the heads of families would sign the union's constitution, each thus becoming responsible for all his famil3^ As soon as the union were formed each of them would pay the amount of at least one share of 50 liras together with a guaranteeing deposit of 5,000 liras. This latter sum would be entered in a current account book which would be delivered to the depositor on the same day. The agri- cultural union would be superintended and inspected by the colon^^'s government. This government would for the first two j^ears freely sup- ph' the seeds of the herbaceous crops to be grown and the plants for lignous plantations. The colony's technical agricultural ofiice would decide what machines were needed on each holding, and the union would deliver them to the cultivators, entering the sum charged for them on the current account books. Each holding would receive from six to ten head of cattle, and even- tually one or two camels and twenty-four sheep, the value of the animals being likewise entered in the current account books. For articles of food each family would have a book and the total sum due for purchases made from the union would be debited to them monthly. The financial resources of 114 ITALIAN SOMALILAXD - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL the union would be constituted b}^ the amount of subscribed and paid-up shares, and each family's guaranteeing deposit of 5,000 liras. The colony's government might grant subsidies to the union during the first five j-ears. Five per cent, on sums to the credit of the cultivators in their current accounts would be paid to them by way of encouragement and 3 per cent, charged on the sums with which they were debited. Eventually the rate of interest on the debit and credit accounts would be the same. All products of the soil would be delivered to the union which would have the necessary warehouses and the other accommodation in which they could be prepared for commercial or industrial use. They would be uti- lized in their entirety, by the sale of primary and secondary products in their natural state, or b}' the submission to essi cation or other processes of pro- ducts (vegetables, fruit, etc.) which could not travel or be kept for any length of time. The quantities delivered would be entered in the current account books, at prices fixed by the administrative council in agreement with the director, a supplementarj^ quota of au}^ larger price ^delded by sale being added when necessary. Thus the agricultural union would discharge to some extent several roles. It would supply first a commercial agency for the purchase and the distribution "to members of live stock, agricultural machines, seeds, plants and other agricultural requisites ; secondly a bank for receiving guarantee and savings deposits and making agricultural avances, like the Italian agri- cultural banks ; thirdl}^ a warehouse for ever>i;hing needed to feed and clothe the cultivators' families ; and fourthly an industrial co-operative pro- ducers' societ}^ for the commercial conversion or preparation of the products of the soil. This union would last for ten years, and would then be renewed in a form modified as experience would dictate. The by-laws of the union should be adapted to local conditions and the laws in force in the colony. The scheme has some further provisions as to the purchase and letting of cultivated land after the first five years of cul- tivation. But this part of the scheme seems to us to have been superse- ded since article 15 of the rules for developing the lands in Italian Somali- land established that concessions would be made for a term of ninety-nine years. The financial part of the scheme presupposes an expenditure on installation of half a million liras, and one of 42,000 liras a j^ear on the working which might after five years be reduced to 32.000 liras. * * : There is no doubt that a prosperous future awaits Italian Somaliland we have seen what elements of wealth the colony contains, what new factors of production and of wealth might be cultivated or called forth LAND TENURE AND COLONIZATION II 5 within it, and all the economic and administrative measures taken to develop these treasures. But that which we said with reference to Erythrea as to the import- ance of the human element applies also to Somaliland. The politics of the native population, misunderstood and neglected in the early period of the Italian occupation of Erythrea, intimately affect the relations be- tween the mother country and the nations on which her civilizing role is exercised and are largety responsible for the result and success of the econo- mic and administrative measures prop.osed for the development of colonial enterprises. MISCELLANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL. BELGIUM. AGRICUIvTURAIy TRAINING FOR PARTI.\I,I,Y DISABI^ED SOI^DIERS. — Communi- cated by M. H. de I^appaient to the Academie iV agriculture en France, at the session of 13 December 1916. «. In organizing technical training for the seriously wounded the Bel- gian government has acted on the f)rinciple that an injured man should, whenever possible, not run the risk of becoming a dead weight on the re- sources of his country, but should still be an appraisable asset, even — in some cases — an element of prosperity. It has therefore been decided to compel the partially disabled to undergo a technical training, suited to the nature of their injuries, the trade they have previously foUowed, and the tastes and aptitudes which may be discovered in them. In August 1915 the work of instalUng the Belgian Mhtar>' Institute for the Technical Training of the SeriousW Wounded on the land of Notre- Dame-de-la-Mere, seven kilometres (i) from Vernon (Eure), was begun. Huts which can be taken to pieces and are of uniform pattern are dis- tributed in three rows separated by well metalled roads. They cover an area of 17,000 square metres (2) and accommodate more than 1200 men, including the permanent staff of the school. The number accommodated will be raised to 2,000. The work necessitates a variety of plant and of labour : for the roads which have to be made a quarrj' has been opened, and its stone is transport- ed by a Decauville way ; land containing too much clay has had to be ren- dered sanitary ; a sj'stem of electricity', seventy kilometres long, has been established to give light to 1,400 lamps and to feed thirty motor-engines in the various workshops, furnishing altogether 158 horse-power. The site of the Institute, in the centre of a forest of 350 hectares (3), made it possible to make a bargain with the owner for the purchase of the (i) I kilometre = 1093.633 yards. (2) I square metre = 10.764 square feet. (3) 1 hectare = 2.47 acres. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICUI.TURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAI, II 7 underwood, in the interests of heating, as well as most of the forest trees. There has ensued real forestry enterprise with the accompanying industry and machinery, and considerable quantities of stakes have been secured. Fortj'-eight different trades are taught, each by a practical workman and demonstrators. In addition to the practical work two hours a day are devoted to courses and technical explanations, given by specialists who, like the overseers, are themselves soldiers, oftenest unfit for service b}' rea- son of wounds or their health. Among the trades taught which are connected with agriculture are cart- er's work, smith's work, the mending of agricultural machines, harness- making, basket-making, the making of packing-cases. Some hectares of uncultived and clayey land have been given up to vegetable growing on a large scale, and it has been necessary to dig, drain and clean these. Heavy manuring and numerous agricultural expedients have produced good returns. A vast kitchen-garden has also been formed, its beds bordered by ready-grown fruit-trees. Outside the central premises of the Institute, in which only some hec- tares of land admit of cultivation, a farm of some twenty hectares at a short distance has been rented ; and there the scientific succession of crops, which pla3's so large a part in kitchen-gardening, is practised, and some good meadows allow a certain number of carefully selected milch-cows to be kept. The average number of wounded men undergoing agricultural or hor- ticultural training is seventy. They are given experience, successively and in order, of all forms of indoor and outdoor work. They are especially trained to prepare and pack vegetables, which are produced largely above the needs of the establishment. At the end of August igi6 the growing vegetables were valued at some 38,000 francs (i). The training given in keeping regular accounts should be noted ; for it is of capital importance to each of the trades taught in the Institute, where the whole industrial enterprise aims at the sale of products, manu- factured and other. Every wounded man receives 0.05 franc per working hour from the time of his arrival, b}^ way of encouragement. Each trade is however divided into an aiDprenticeship and a productive section, and when a man is fit to pas? into the latter his wages increase progressively until they reach or even surpass the level of those of uninjured workmen in the same trade. '■' These productive sections ", says the technical director in his report, " have brought in more than 620,000 francs for manufactured articles.. The importance of keeping accounts can he estimated when it is stated that the turnover for the past year was 950,000 francs ". Finally we note that an agricultural orphanage has just been estab- lished, in which orphans of the war will enjoy conditions analogous to those of the partially disabled men, receiving a practical and technical agricul- tural training. 3 (i) I franc = 9 — rf. at par. IlS NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTUR.\L ECONOMY IN GENERAL FRANXE. THE DEPARTMENT FOR CIVIL AND MILITARY VEGETABLE GARDENS. This department was recently set up within the Ministry of Agricul- ture, united to the Ministr\- of War, and was placed under the direction of R. Maxinie Ducroq, president of the enterprise for workmen's gardens at Lille. Its chief object is to provoke and encourage the formation of vast ve- getable gardens on the abandoned lands : i) By means of the depots of arm}' corps and their sections, the sen-' try-posts of territorials guarding roads and communications, and the hos- pitals and other mihtary establishments, in which men are retained by their duties and whence they cannot be sent away on leave or for agricul- tural employment, but where none the less they dispose daily of some hours of leisure ; 2) Bj^ means of the civil population of large towns and the neigh- bourhoods of these. In 1916, 5,622 militar}' vegetable gardens, having an approximate total area of 2,000 hectares (i) and able to yield about 13 million francs (2) a 3^ear wese formed by these means. In order largely to develop this first success, a staff of seventj- mobi- lized men has been instructed at the Ministry of Agriculture and has been commissioned to go through all France, encouraging by lectures, advice and other measures the gardening by depots ; and it is hoped that the exis- ting numbei of gardens will thus be multiplied by five or even ten in 1917. Besides vegetable gardens it was recommended that military piggeries should be instituted, in order to utilize greasy water and other waste food. Almost all the depots now keep pigs in this way, and some of them con- stantly have in their sties about a hundred pigs, the meat of which does not cost them more than 1.25 francs a kilogramme (3). The civil vegetable-gardens have also acquired a considerable impor- tance. Nine recently formed committees share the task of cultivating the lands attached to the fortifications of Paris in which 3,500 gardens have been established. But the number of applications is much above this fi- gure, and the project was conceived of causing some of the abandoned lands in the neighbourhood of the citj'^ to be cultivated by the population of Paris. A meeting of the mayors of the communes of the department of Seine was therefore held at the Ministry of Agriculture on 22 Februaiy 1917 and was followed by the formation of several local organizing commit- tees. Already analogous committees have been formed in a certain number of these conmmnes to distribute their uncultivated lands among their in- (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. (2) I franc = 9 ^/^d at par. (3) I kilogramme = 2 ^/g lbs. NOTICES REI^ATING TO AGRICULTURAX ECONOMY IN GENERAL II 9 habitants. One of them has distributed 300 gardens, of 300 square metres (i) each, to as many necessitous famihes. The movement is spreading to the large provincial towns. Some of them have resumed on a far larger scale the culture which they undertook in 1916 at the expense of the municipality, and they have without excep- tion obtained the best results. Further by the despatches of 30 December 1916 and 19 January 1917 the ]\Iinister of War decreed that a certain number of mobilized men should in each district be commissioned for three months in the year to provoke and encourage the formation and development of military vegetable gar- dens. These mobilized men went through a course at the ^Ministry of Agri- culture which ended on 4 February 1917, and then departed to their dis- tricts where most of them at once began work. Since the despatches mentioned were variously interpreted, in some dis- tricts the minister specified their intention as follows : i) F)ach of the men concerned, except such as have been noted as un- suitable by the Ministry of Agriculture and therefore replaced, should re- ceive as soon as he reaches his district, from the general commanding it, an order allowing him to go and come freely within its limits. The three months for which he is comnu'ssioned start on the da}- on which this order is remitted to him. 2) From the date on which this order is remitted to him the lecturer is under the orders only of the general or generals to whose subdivisions he has been assigned, is in direct correspondence with them, and addresses his reports to them directly. 3) For the time for which he is commissioned the lecturer nmst not be expected to render other service. 4) In every place lectures must be delivered to the chiefs of united units and not to each unit separately, and must precede the visits to the varioiis military formations. 5) With a view to these visits a lecturer is supplied without delay with a complete list of the military units, detachments and establishments within the district assigned to him. In virtue of a decision of the Minister of War on 18 February 1917 the head of the Department ot Civil and IMilitary Vegetable Gardens at the Ministry of Agriculture has been entrusted with the local control of the exe- cution of instructions a])plicable to military vegetable gardens, the verifi- cation of results obtained, and the superintendence of the military lectu- rers commissioned for the relevant work of propaganda. (i) I square metre = 10.764 square feet. 120 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL NEW ZEALAND. SETTLEMENT OF DISCHARGED SOLDIERS ON THE LAND. — The Journal of Ihe'Board of Agriculture. London, October 1916. In New Zealand the problem of lielping the discharged soldier over the period of transition from military to civil life has been attacked with commendable promptness and thoroughness. At the outset, owing to the novelty of the work and the necessity of improvising the entire machi- nery, many difficulties had to be faced. The Discharged Soldiers' Inform- ation Department, the department of State specialh^ formed to deal with the matter, has however surmounted most of these difficulties and the work is now organized on a satisfactory basis. According to the first report of the department, which was issued in May, its procedure is, briefly, as follows. The names, addresses and other ge- neral particulars as to returning soldiers are collected before the transports reach the landing ports and are registered on cards. The cards are then sorted according to the various districts and a confidential schedule is sent to a local committee. When the soldier is eventually discharged from military service he is interviewed by an officer of the department who reports any particulars which are likeh^ to be of use in finding him employ- ment. With the assistance of the local committee a determined effort is then made to secure employment for those who require it. The employment of soldiers on the land naturally forms an important part of the work of the department. To meet the case of soldiers who have had no experience in farming, arrangements have been made with the Depart- ment of Agriculture to undertake the training of a limited number of men on the various State farms in general farming, dair\' farming, fruit farm- ing, poultry and bee keeping, etc. It was thought that partially disabled men in receipt of pensions might reasonabl}^ be expected to desire to take up small sections under the land settlement scheme, for the purpose of poul- try raising and other light branches of farm work, and that in these cases a course of practical instruction would often save loss of time and money and consequent discouragement. Up to the present time the opportun- ities afforded have not been taken advantage of, the men — almost with- out exception — desiring employment of an immediately remunerative character. vState assistance to New Zealand soldiers wishing to settle on the land is however by no means confined to courses of instruction . By an Act passed in October 1915 and entitled the Discharged Soldiers' Settlement Act, 1915, a discharged soldier is given a number of advantages. Under this Act land may be taken up in two wa^^s. Crown or settlement land may be set apart for selection only by discharged soldiers, or it may be disposed of to them under special conditions. In either case the Department of Lands is empower- ed to remit — wholly or in part and for such periods as it thinks fit — any NOTICES REI,ATING TO AGRICU I.TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAI. 121 rent paj'able by a discharged soldier, or may postpone the date for the pay- ment of the rent. When held under special conditions the soldier maj' receive financial assistance to enable him to bring his farm into such a state that he can make a living from it. ' Land may be disposed of to discharged soldiers either by way of sale or by lease. When sold the price is fixed by the Land Board. If disposed of on terms of deferred pa^mient the purchaser has to pay a deposit of 5 per cent, of the purchase money, the balance being paid in equal annual in- stalments with interest at 5 per cent. When let the term maj'' be up to sixt3'-six years with a perpetual right of renewal for further successive terms. The rent will be determined by the board and is not in any case to be more than 4 14 P^r cent, of the capital value of the land. The lessee may at any time during the continuance of the lease acquire the fee simple of the land. Under section 6 the Minister of Lands maj' assist an applicant in the clearing, fencing and general improvement of the land, the erection of build- ings, and the purchase of implements, stock, seed, trees and any other things which may be deemed necessary for the successful occupation of the land. The rate of interest is to be fixed by the minister, but in cases of hardship he has power to dispense wholty or in part with the payment of interest. The total of the advances made to one person is not to exceed £500. No land let or sold to a discharged soldier under the Act can be transferred until the expiry of ten years from the date of the sale or the beginning of the lease. According to the first report on the working of the Act 500,000 acres of land have been provisionalh' set apart for discharged soldiers. Of this area 67,855 acres have formally been proclaimed under the Act. It has been decided to cut up some blocks of land into suitable sections and, be- fore finally settling soldiers on them, to eftect such improvements as will enable selectors to make a living off their sections. As far as possible soldiers will be employed in effecting these improvements. For fruit farm- ing it has been decided to plant areas with fruit trees, particularly apples. RUSSIA. THE FORESTS OF FINNISH TOWNS. — Uppsatser i skogsbruk ; Helsingfors. Septcmlit-r 1916 ; For landtmannahcm ; Helsingfors, September 1916. In 1915 the Central Communal Office undertook an enquiry as to forest economy in the towns, sending a detailed form of questions to all the towns of the country. Only Kemi and Mariehamn made no response. The results of this enquiry have been published in a stud}^ which forms part of a se- ries showing the special researches of the Finnish Forestry Society, and which is also among the publications of the Central Communal Office. According to the information supplied by the financial commissions 122 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL of the towns, the forests of the different towns had in 1915 the following areas : Kajana 9521.01 hectares (i) Tornea 5430.29 Kuopio 3876.42 Uleaborg 3485-57 Gamlakarleby 3149.48 Lovisa 2670.82 Raumo 2502.57 Heinola 2418.68 Kristinestad 2303.00 Ekenas 1847.38 Xykarleby 1638,60 Helsingfors 1536.00 Joensuu 1513.70 Viborg 1507.98 Nyslott 1450.00 Hango 1189.04 Vasa 1183.59 Brahestad 1044.50 Jakobstad 980.48 Kexholm 865.45 Tammerfors . . . ' 845.46 Nystad 833.92 Tavastehus 808.75 Idensalmi 736.38 Borga 719-33 Kasko 682.21 Lahtis 678.77 J^'vaskyla 653.26 Bjorneborg 642.82 St. Michel 598.35 Fredrikshamn 586.00 Abo 575-22 Willman strand 574-^7 Sordavala 367.40 Kotka 353-60 Xadendal 170.46 The total area of the communal forests is thus about 60,000 hectares. The forest law of 1886 compelled the towns to draw up rules of forest economy for the forests on their donation lands (2) and to derive profit from (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. (2) Landed property gremted to the towns by the State. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 1 23 them in accordance with these rules. If the area of the woodland be one hundred hectares or more the Forest Administration must advise concerning the projected rules before the municipal council accepts them. Seme towns however have still no rules of forest economy. The following notes shows the importance of the Finnish communal forests to the economy of urban communes. The towns of Kjana, Tornea, Kuopio, Gamlakarleb5% Kristinestad, Ekenas, Lovisa, Heinola, Nykarleby, Hango, Kexholm, St. Michel and Xadendal can take from their own forests only all the wood they need for building but they may not sell wood. The towns of Raumo, Brahestad, Jakobstad and Idensalmi take from their own forests all the carpentering wood they need but do not sell any wood. The towns of Uleaborg, Nyslott, N^-stad, Tavastehus, Borga, Kask5, Jyvaskyla and Willmanstrand have sold building wood but have on the other hand made several purchases of wood to meet their own needs. The towns of Joensuu, Vasa, Lahtis, Bjor- neborg and Fredrikshamn have not been able to sell any wood but have been obliged, on the contrary, to bu}^ it. Finally four towns — Kotka, Abo, Sordavala and Mariehamm, have derived no economic profit from their forests. If we classify the towns according to the net income they obtain from their forests they should be placed in the following order : The first is the town of Jyvaskyla which in the quinquennial period 1910-1914 derived from its forests an average net income of 34.73 francs (i) a hectare. The second is the town of Kuopio, if we include in the net in- come the value of the wood with which the town has met its own needs. The year 1914 then yielded a net income of 30.63 francs a hectare, sales alone giving an average net income in this year of 14.63 francs a hectare. Gamlakarley should probably be placed third, and Borga, with its average of 23.42 francs, fourth. There follow Kristinestad — 22.18 francs; S^- Michel — 19. 11 francs; Lovisa 17.81 francs (2); Kasko 15.32 francs; Nadendal — 13.74 francs; Nyslott — 8.79 francs ; Kexholm — 6.14 francs (2); Ekenas — 5.64 francs; Uleaborg — 5.49 francs (2) ; Hango — 3.04 francs; Vasa — 2.44 francs ; Raumo — 2.26 francs (3) ; Lahtis — 2.17 francs (3) ; Tavastehus — 2.21 francs ; Tornea — 2.09 francs ; Kajana — 1.99 francs (2); Joensuu 1.74 francs (3) ; Nykarleby 1.59 francs ; Viborg — 1.22 francs and Bjorneborg — 1.09 francs. The town of Helsingfors suffered a loss of 3 centimes a hectare and that of Fredrikshamm one of 53 centimes a hectare. (i) I franc = 9 ^5 d- ^t P^r. {2) Income from sales. (3) In 1914. 124 I^OTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL the position and the activity of the grain elevators of the govern- ment and the railway companies. Sources : i) A. XtopoiueHKO : " .'3aeBaTopHoe zitao bt, Pocciii bt. 1915 rojy ,. (A. Doros- chenko : " The Work of the Elevators in Russia in 1915 ") in B'hcTHiiKb OiinaHCOBt, IIpoMMiiiJieHHOCTH H ToprOBJiii (Messenger of Finances,. Industry and Commerce) Nos. 31, 32 — 31 July, 13 August and 7/20 August 1916. 2) ToprOBO-IIpoMbiinJieHHaH Fasexa (Gazette of Commerce and Industry) Nos. 201, 203 — 17,27 and 17/30 August 1916. If the two great agrarian reforms, that of 1S61 and that of 1905, had effect, apart from their social and poUtical influences, on factors which bore on agricultural production, the establishment of grain elevators was destined to be among the most important influences which enhanced the commer- cial value and the profitableness of the harvest jdelds when once they had been obtained. Production and markets had to be brought nearer togeth- er, the middlemen eliminated if possible, and grain of better quality' and in a purer state more evenly brought into trade. These ideals were con- ceived in Russia as early as the fortieth year of last centur>' (i), but it was only in its eightieth 3'ear, after the advent of overseas competition, that the idea of covering the Russian State with a system of elevators really gained ground. Railway companies and private persons then undertook the erection of grain elevators. The first of them date from 1891 and were four in num- ber, situated in Rjashsk (Government of Rjasan) and Koslov (Government of Tambov) , the warehousing capacity in both these places being of 300, 000 ptids (2), and in Dankov and I,ebedjan (Government of Tambov), in both of which the warehousing capacitj' was of 200,000 puds. In 1897 seven elevators were at work and in 1902 twenty-seven. Before March 1897, the date at which the erection of elevators by the means of the State Bank begaU; sixty-one elevators of the railway companies and of private individ- uals existed and their total warehousing capacity was of 23,524,000 puds. In addition there was an elevator of the zemstvo administration of Jeletz (Government of Orel) which could store 672,000 puds of grain. The largest of these elevators, eight in ntimber, were erected in the harbours, namely : (i) See " Loans granted by the State Bank on Security of Grain and the Establishment of Grain Elevators in Russia, " Monthly Bulletin of Economic and Social Intelligence, March 1914, page 85. (2) I pud = 40 lbs. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL L2=, In Petrograd . 2 elevators having a storage capacity of 3,200,000 puds " Revel ... I " " " " 250,000 " Vindava . . i " " " " 2,362,000 " " Riga . . . T " . " " " 750,000 " " Novorossijsk i " " " " 3,000,000 " Nikolaev . . i " " " " 1,750,000 " Odessa . . i " " " " 1,000,000 " Total 8 12,312,000 The storage capacity of the fifty-four elevators which were situated in the interior was of 11,884,000 puds. Individual elevators among these differ very much as to the amount of grain they can receive : it varies from 150,000 or 200,000 puds to 1,000,000 puds — the estimate being for r^'e — in Moscow. Judged by the num]:)er of times their contents change hands during a trading season the biggest elevators attain the best results : thus in Mos- cow this was effected 1.74 times, in Koslov (the nearest elevators being included in the calculation) 1.81 times. Two other elevators in fertile dis- tricts which chiefly serve purposes of loading also work very well. All the others, that is the smaller elevators, have difficulty in obtaining a like success, as appears in their financial results. Only the elevators in Moscow and Koslov have attained to a profit. All others on the Rjasan-Ural line brought a loss to their companies. Year Receipt Expenditure Proiit Loss 1912 225,041 roubles (i) 199,215 roubles 25,826 roubles — roubles 1913 163,157 " 204,077 " — " 40,920 1914 218,483 " 247,042 " _ " 28,559 That the railway'- companies met with so little success in their erec- tion of elevators is partly due to the fact that these for the mcst part were built on sites chosen with little regard to their activities, and were connect- ed neither with the banks or the exchanges, and that each of them work- ed for itself alone, in isolation, the companies following onl)' their own special and individual aims without seeking to influence the total trade in grain. The employment of the elevators by the population was therefore in no sense extensive. In 1897, 11,107,000 puds of grain were brought to the elevators of the Rjasan-Ural line, which had a storage capacity of 6,350,000 puds; ten years later, in 1907,. 10,452,000 puds were brought to (i) I rouble = about 2s i^d at par. 126 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAT< them. Thus not only was' there no improvement: there was retrogression. Even the amount of 1907 has not been reached of late years. Grain brought Year to the Elevators 1912 5,807,800 puds I913 6,440,300 ) IQI4 8,446,500 >i These figures shows indeed some progress, but 11,107,000 puds, the amount of 1897, has not since been equalled. To make the elevators more effective for purposes of trade, and to heighten their activities as regarded both quantity and quality of grain, the government decided to establish its own sj^stem of elevators by means of the .State Bank. Hence arose : in 1912 3 elevators having a storage capacity of. . . 2,500,000 puds " 1913 6 " " " " ... 5,700,000 " 1914 9 " " " " ... 5,050,000 '' 1915 12 " " " " ... 7,500,000 In addition in these same 3'ears the State Bank acquired three eleva- tors having a storage capacit}' of 850,000 puds from the Rjasan-Ural Rail- way Company, and in the beginning of 191 6 one elevator having a storage capacit}^ of 1,000,000 puds (Moscow). In the beginning of April 1916 the State Bank erected an elevator able to receive 600,000 puds. Thus altogether there arose thirty-five elevators having a total storage capacity of 23,200,000 puds. In addition thirty-four were being built and were more or less completed. It was decided on 17 June 1916 to erect for the grain districts of the north east and the south west and for the black earth district seventy-seven elevators and granaries able to receive 62,750,000 puds. Through the medium of the State Bank it has also been planned to cover Siberia with a system of elevators, placing in Novo-Xikolajevik (Co\-ernment of Tomsk,) where the trade in grain is ver}^ great, an eleva- tor to hold 2,000,000 puds, and at the station of Kulomsino, at the junc- tion of the Omsk-Jekateripiburg and Tcheljabinsk - Irkutsk railways, one to hold 1,500,000 puds and more. The existing granaries in .Siberia numbered seventy-seven in the mid- dle of July 1915 — they are said since to have increa.sed — , had a storage ca]ntcity of 6,704,000 puds, and were subject to the Colonization Adminis- tration. The activities of the elevators of the State Bank cannot be measured by their financial results, as can those of a private company, for they are proportionate not to profits but to the efforts made to organize the home trade in grain on a regular plan and to direct it to right paths. Financial points of view should be diregarded especially at the present time, in which , all elevators have been placed under military direction. Nevertheless in XOTICKS RKI,ATINa TO AGRICIU.TURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL 1 27 IQ15 several elevators attained to very favourable balance-sheets, as ap- pears from the following figures. Elevators Profits Storage capacity 1 (Commission not deducted) Zemstvo Commission Net Profits Gr5'asi (GjOV. of Tambov) . Tolkaj ( 1^ » Voronesh). Liski ( >. » » ). Neprik ( » » vSamara) . MiUcrovo (District of the Danube) Bosatoe (Gov. of Samara) . SorotPhinskaja (Gov. of S:v 1,700,000 Puds I 71,853 Roubles; 30,559 Roubles I 41,294 Roubles 300,000 » 500,000 > 300,000 a 600,000 » 300,000 » 7,868 4,186 13.059 18,991 6,561 2,431 2,433 4,862 1,307 3,051 1.755 11,049 10,626 14,129 The elevators are developing a very valuable activity in the service of the mihtary authorities. In the region of Tambov, for example, where the State Bank possesses four elevators, 17 per cent, of all bought grain passed through these from i January until i July 1915, and 28 per cent, from I July 1915 to i Januan.^ 1916. In the south-eastern region 38 per cent, of all bought grain was brought to the elevators from i July 1915 to 1 June 1916 and 45 per cent, of oats and barley. Grain when received in the elevators is very carefully dried, cleaned several times over, and carefully sorted. Drying machines have been installed for twenty-four elevators. The building of the elevator in Nabe- reshniie Tshelni, now nearly completed, will enable the total number of drying machines to deal with 3,000 puds an hour. As regards the number of times the contents of the elevators change hands in a season this is effected four or even five times in the case of the large erections near railwa}^ jimctions, and from one and a half times to twice in that of the .small local elevators. In order to co-ordinate the ac- tivities of elevators and more and more itself to control them, the vState Bank will erect them in future only on a large scale. The smaller and lo- cal granaries in the rural districts will continue to be decentralized and will be conducted by the zemstvo administrations and the co-operative soci- eties. Thtis the countryman, by the medium of his co-operative society or the zemstvo, can convey his grain to the State Bank's elevator which makes the direct connection with the world's markets. All that has been said makes clear that we have here a means of giving a firm basis to the Russian trade in grain and a promise of a continually improving output of Russian grain on foreign markets. RUGGKRI ALFREDO, gereute responsabilc (c) Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases. 1. t,B Service de Protection contre les maladies des plantes et lbs INSECTES NtrisiBLES DANS LES DivERS PAYS (The Prescut Organization of the Services for the Control of Plant Diseases and Insect Pests in the Different Countries). (1914, 350 pages, 4to) Fn. 4.00 a. PRODUCTION ET CONSOMMATION DES EnGRAIS CHIMIQUES DANS LE MONDB (Production and Consumption of Chemical Manures in the World). (Second Edition, 1914, 162 pages, 5 diagrams, 2 maps, i6mo) 3.50 3. I,A LUTTE CONTRE LES SAUTERELLES DANS LES DIVERS PAYS(The Campaign against l,ocusts in Various Regions) (1916, 188 pages, i6mo) » 3.50 {d) Publications of the Bureau of Economic and Social Intelligence. I'. I,'activit6 de l'Institdt International d'Agriculture dans le Do- MAINE de la COOP6rATION, DE L'ASSURANCE ET DU Cr6dIT AGRIC0LE9 (The Work of the International Institute of Agriculture in the Field of Agricultural Co-operation, Insurance and Credit). (In French, German and Italian). (1912, 34 pages, i6mo) 0.50 a. Monographs on Agricultural Co-operation in Various Countries, Vol. I. (1911, 451 pages, i6mo). (In English and French) ■ 3.53 Do. Vol. II. (1915, 213 pages i6ino). (In English and French) ... 1 3.50 3. An Outline of the European Co-operative Credit Systems (Second Edition, 1913, 72 pages, i6mo) • 0.50 4. 1,'ORGANISATION de la ST-iVTISTlQUE DE LA COOPERATION AGRICOLE D.\N9 QUELQUES P.4.YS (The Organization of the Statistics of Agricultural Co- operation in Certain Countries). (1911, 163 pages, 8vo) 1.50 5. ly'ASSURANCE-GRfeLE D.'UVS QUELQUES PAYS ET SES PROBL^MES (lUaUranCe against Hail in Some Countries and its Problems). (191 1, 110 pages, 8vo) . . • 1.50 6. AGRICULTUR.'iL CREDIT AND CO-OPERATION IN ITALY: SHORT GUIDE TO RURAL Co-OPERATION IN ITALY (in English, 35 pages and in Italian, 34 pages, i6mo) 1 0.25 (e) Other publications. I. l^'lNSTiTUT International d'Agriculture, son organisation, son activit6, sesr6sultats (The International Institute of Agriculture, its Organization, Activity, and Results). (1914,31 pages, in English, French and Italian; illustr.) Frs. i — 2. I" workers, and the paid staff of the central banks. All the central banks were frequently inspected by the Registrar and his staff. § 4. The CENTRAL PROVINCES AND BERAR. The progress of the co-operative movement in the Central Provinces and Berar is seen from the following statement : Class of Society No. of Societies No. of Members Workin ? Capital 1913-1914 1914-1915 1913-191+ 1914-1915 1913-1914 1914-1915 Central societies. . . Agricultural societies Non-agricultural so- cieties 38 2,087 88 46 2,158 93 6,131 34.313 1.778 7.074 37.053 2,023 Rs. 38,37.4" 25,76,238 96,284 Rs. 43,22,056 28,21,670 1.17,595 Total . . . 2,213 2,297 42,222 46,150 65,09,933 72,61,321 PROGRESS OF AGRICUI^TURAI, CO-OPERATION Central Societies. — On 30 June 1915 there were one provincial bank, twenty-nine central banks, fifteen agricultural unions and one Cen- tral Provinces Union of Co-operative Banks. The working capital of the pro\dncial bank had increased from Rs. 12, 22, 450 to Rs. 13,44,315 and the deposits from Rs. 5,35,933 to Rs. 9,(86,796. The working capi- tal of the central banks had risen from Rs. 25,86,613 to Rs. 28,37,460, of which latter sum the share capital formed 21 per cent., deposits by members 13 per cent., local deposits by non- members 27 per cent., and loans from the provincial bank 37 per cent. The interest charged by the central banks on loans was generally 9 per cent, while they paid 6 per cent, on de- posits. The provincial bank lent money to societies at 7 per cent, and paid 5 per cent, interest on deposits. The Central Provinces Union of Co- operative Banks had continued to give valuable help to the Registrar in securing unity of aim and effort. Its total income for the year was Rs. 50,411. Failures of crops led to numerous renewals of loans. Agricultural Societies. — The number of agricultural credit societies based on unlimited liability rose from 2,083 to 2,154— 127 being newly re- gistered in 1914-1915. 2,013 societies had been affihated to central banks on 30 June 1915. Two cattle-breeding societies were working satisfac- torily, one at Nawagaon and one at Khandwa. Audit and Inspection. — The societies were inspected and their books audited by the Registrar, his assistant, the chief auditor and his staff. Considerable work of this sort was done by the Union. § 5. Ajmer-Merwara. The following statement shows the comparative progress of co-operation in Ajmer-Merwara in 1913-1914 and 1914-1915. Class of Society No. of Societies No. of Members Working Capital 1913-1914 1914-1915 1913-1914 1914-19x5 1913-1914 1914-1915 Central societies. . . Agricultural societies. Non-agricultural so- cieties 5 352 5 355 774 10,387 841 11,264 Rs. 7,50,322 7,35,509 Rs. 8,15,242 7,03,016 Total . . . 357 360 11,161 12,105 14.85.831 15,18,258 Central Societies. — There were five central banking unions in 1914- 1915 as in 1913-1914. Ax the end of the former year 344 societies had been affiliated to the banking unions and were financed by them, the rate of interest charged being 10 per cent. The net profit of the banks BRITISH INDIA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION was Rs. 21,885 ^s againt Rs. 23,026 in the previous year. The reserve fund amounted to Rs. 14,320 as against Rs. 7,373 in 1913-1914. Agricultural Societies. — In 1914-1915 only three societies were re- gistered, two in the Ajmer district and one in Berar. The share capital of the agricultural societies rose from Rs. 1,23,039 to Rs. 1,68,809, and government loans decreased from Rs. 31,667 to Rs. 21,067. The societies generally utilized their reserve funds themselves. Auditing and inspecting were done by the Registrar and his staff. § 6. COORG. No new credit societj' was registered in 1914-1915. The amount of working capital rose from Rs. 1,06,020 to Rs. 1,15,400 and the reserve fund from Rs. 18,106 to Rs 23,514. The number of cattle insurance societies increased from nine to ten; 434 heads of cattle were insured ; and the reserve fund of the insurance societies rose from Rs. 188 to Rs. 590. Nine co-operative credit societies resolved in 1914-1915 that the divi- dend due to shareholders should thenceforth be employed on insuring their cattle. The grain bank worked satisfactoril}^ and its profit for the year was Rs. 594-12-5. The repa^-ment of loans was not encouraging, the loans outstanding at the 3'ear's end being" 12 per cent of their total amount as against 6 y^ per cent, in the previous year. The societies charged in- terest at the rate of 12 i^ per cent on their loans and paid from 5 to 6 ^ per cent, on the money they borrowed. The committee and controllers managed the societies satisfactorily All accounts were audited by the registrar personally. ITALY. COI^IvRCTIVE DAIRIES. •SOURCES : Camparini (I,ui.gi) and Ruscelt.oni (Alfredo) : Manuale per le latterie. Appunti di legislazione, amministrazione, contabilita {Dairy Manual. Notes on legislation, administration, and book keeping) Published by the " Unione Nazionale delle I' of Soresina, the largest in Itah', to which we will devote a special paragraph. The co-operative dairies in the province of Brescia number more than fifty ; those in the province of Bergamo more than thirty (2). In the lat- (i) These data are approximate, it being in practice difficult to establish precise statistics for these societies, especially such of them as are virtuallj- constituted but are often at work only for a few months, according to the district in which they are situated, dissolving at the end of this period and subsequently reconstituting themselves after a short inter\-al. (2) Detailed information as to the collective dairies of lyomliardy will be found in the report of the jury for the prize competition opened in 1 9 1 4 by the Societd agraria di Lombardia for dairies founded in this region before 191 3 and dealing with an average quantity of no more than 15 quintals (i quintal = 220 lbs.) of milk. Twenty-one societies took part in this competition. COLI^ECTIVE DAIRIES II ter province the dairies have united in a federation with the object of sell- ing in common butter produced in excess of local needs, in order to obtain higher prices by making collective offers. In the province of Mantua the societies for the sale of milk have also united in a federation which is at- tached to the agricultural union of Ouistello. They are foimd extensively. In Venetia co-operative cheesemaking is commonest in \'icenza (for- ty-two dairies) and Treviso (twenty-one dairies). Among these dairies one is very important, that at Soligo which has establishments at Soligo, Pieve de Soligo and Colle San Martino. In the province of Udine no count can now be kept of the dairies : every village has its collective cheese-fac- tory — there are more than 300 of them. In the region of Eelluna there are as many as 160 of these dairies. The first federation of co-operative dairies was founded in this province and has premises at Agordo. Its object is the sale of butter produced by adherent organizations, and it still exists and is working magnificently. In Emilia some ten dairies are found in the province of Parma — most of them let to business men ; there are twenty co-operative dairies in the province of Reggio (i) and four in that of Bologna. In southern and central Italy there are very few of these cheesemaking industries (2). In Sardinia there is only the dairy of Bortigalli. Hence it is necessary to intensify the propaganda for the formation of these co- operative societies in the southern provinces and the islands. Co-operative organizations have also been formed to provide milk for the large urban centres, and are constituted by producers, an exception being the Cooperative del lattc of Milan which is a mixed association of con- From the report (BollMino deW Agricoltiira,nos. 31 and 32, Milan, 31 July and 7 August 1914) we learn that most of them were of recent foundation. We note however that a few were older, like those of Morbegno, Ponte and Tirano which have existed for more than thirty years. All are co-operative societies except that at Casto which follows the systems of manufacture by turns, and that at Tirano which follows two systems, that of co-operation and that of manu- facture by turns. All but three have merely a constitution de facto. The building belongs to the society at Gordona (50,000 liras), at Morbegno (18,000 liras) etc. The quantity of milk contributed varies from ontf quintal a day (Valmores) to 1 2 quintals (EUo) . This milk is treated by experts who oftcAi have a diploma for special courses in cheesemaking. The machines and implements are those ordinarily foimd and form in many cases a very modest equipment ; in some they are hired or let by the members. The machines are worked by hand or electricity. The book-keeping of many dairies is excellent, being simple and complete ; but m some cases it is insufficient, the defect being rather personal than one of method. (i) For the organization of cheesemaking in the province of Reggio Emilia see " I^'industria casearia nella provinda di Reggio Emilia. Quadri statistid con note illustrative (The Cheese- making Industry in the Promnce of Reggio Emilia. Statistical Tables with Explanatory Notes), Prof. Cav. Giuseppe F.^scetti . Published by the Chamber of Commerce and Industry of Reggio EmDia. Typ. Bondavilli, 191 5. N (2) Recently the Latteria sociale camerine'ie was constituted at Camerino. Its object is to supply the population with a wholesome and pure product, inspected by the Office of Ilvgiene, and to intensity milk production in order that it may keep pace with the demand for dair>' produce. 12 ITALY - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION stimers and producers. We should note the co-operative societies of milk producers of Brescia, Tortona, Rome and Turin, as well as that of Milan which we have just cited. In Genoa there is an agriciiltural consortium (i) which provides the town with the milk it receives from agricultural members. The service for selling the milk is admirabl}' organized b}^ the consortium. The experiment ma}- be called the largest and best of its kind hitherto made in the country. Most Italian collective dairies, like those of which we have spoken, are on the system of manufacture b}' turns, which is still the commonest, but they are gradually being replaced by co-operative dairies having a small production. "The dair}- of primitive form, working on the system of turns ", says Cerlini in the study we have cited, " should succeed in meet- ing better the fresh needs which follow on the change from this to the co- operative form, as gradually the agricultural conditions of the districts in which it is situated are transformed b}' new systems of agriculture and intensified production, and as zootechnical conditions are modified by an improvement in cattle-breeding aimed at increasing the yield of milk. It is not only the conversion of the milk and the distribution of the product which is now desired : a larger quantity' of milk is used in the dair^^ and consequenth' its conversion results in a larger quantity- of dairy products, which therefore have to be sold to outsiders so that the milk realizes a price paid to the members no longer in cheese but in cash ". Dairies of the average tj'pe are found more or less everj^where in Upper Italy, from Friulia to the valley of Aosta in Upper Ivombardy and Emilia : on an average from three to six thousand quintals of milk are treated in them annually, on well arranged special premises, supplied with modern implements and utensils, in which scientific methods are followed. In the region of Emilia, which is that in which co-operative dairies of the modern type are most extensively found, and especiall}^ in the district of Reggio, dairies treating large quantities of milk are also found. For example in 191 3 the dairy of IMassenzatico treated 6,993 quintals of milk. In eight years it has been possible to obtain results allowing of production on this scale, although at first only 3,425 quintals were treated. Other dairies of the average type are found in the provinces of Reggio, Modena and Parma. In the provinces of Vicenza, Treviso and Udine, in the dis- trict of Novara and in Upper Piedmont organizations of the average type are also found, scattered here and there among innumerable very small dairies. § 3. A TYPICAL EXAMPLE OF CO-OPERATIVK CHEESEMAKING. Such an example is provided by the Latteria Sociale Cooperativa di Soresina in the province of Cremona. This societj' has incontestably one (i) See in this connection Monthly Bulletin of Economic and Social Intelligence, December I9i5,pagc33," The Organization of the Agricultural Consortium of Genoa for the Sale of INIilk". COLIHHaHCOBTj ripoMbimJieHHOCTH H ToproBJiii {Messeni^er of Finances, In- dustry and Commerce) No. 44, 30 October/12 November 1916. Petrograd. IIpaBiiTeJibCTBeHHHri: BtCTHiiKt {Government Messenger) No. 273, 21 December 1916- 3 January 1917. Petrograd. § I. Institutions of popular credit in general. Present circumstances have not stopped the development of small credit in Russia but have merely made it slower. This circumstance may be said to have favoured establishments of which the previous growth had been very rapid. Their comparative numerical decrease has been count- erbalanced b}' a firmer economic position and a more extensive social influence. According to the Messenger of Small Credit the.foUowing new establish- ments were founded between 1914 and 1916 : Number of Year Foundations I914 1,606 1915 956 1916 (i July). 406 The pre\dous average was 2;000. The new foundations were distrib- uted as follows among the different types of institutions on i January and I July in each year : 1914 rgij 1916 I II I I.I January July January July January July Co-operative credit so- cieties 9.536 10,401 10,687 11,176 11,412 11,649 Deposit and loan funds 3,479 3,728 3,815 3,983 4,042 4,195 Funds of Zemstvos , 203 215 232 239 248 266 Federations of co-op- erative credit societies II II II 28 62 84 Total 13,029 14,355 14-745 15426 15,764 16,194 20 RUSSIA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The number of the small credit establishments is seen to have passed between i July 1914 and i July 1916 from 14,355 to 16,194, that is to have increased by 1,739. The increase of the federations of co-operative cre- dit societies from eleven to eighty-four should be especially noticed. § 2. The co-operative credit societies and the DEPOSIT AND lyOAN Funds. a) Number, members and capital in shares. Of the two types of co-operative societies it is those for credit which have most increased, in point of number, of their membership and of their circulating capital. Saving 2.6 per cent, of them which have an urban character they are situated in the country almost exclusively. On the other hand almost half the number (44.6 per cent.) of the deposit and loan funds are in the towns of the south and south-east of Russia. I July I January i July i January 1914 1915 1915 1916 Number of co-operative societies : Credit 10,401 10,687 11,176 11,412 Deposit and loan . . 3,728 3,815 3,983 4,042 Total .... * 14,129 14,502 15,159 15,454 Number of members : Co-operative credit societies 6,948,000 7,228,000 7,714,000 7,787,000 Savings and loan funds 2,199,000 2,261,000 2,306,000 2,298,000 Total .... 9,147,000 9,489,000 10,020,000 10,085,000 Circulating capital (in terms of thousands of roubles) : Co-operative credit , societies 428,173 382,335 468,138 452,909 Deposit and loan funds 344,989 327,712 341,212 330.950 Total .... 773,162 710,047 809,350 783,859 On I July 1916 the institutions for co-operative small credit compris- ed more than ten milUon members, allowing an average of six persons POPULAR CO-OPERATIVE CREDIT 21 for each hoiisehold. This is to say that more than a tliird of the whole Russian population belonged to them. The membership of each co-operative societj^ increased at the fol- lowins; average rate : 1912 1913 1914 1915 40 47 46 51 The number of the members of the deposit and loan funds which reached 595 in 1915 has since been slightly reduced. These funds are less popular than the co-operative credit societies. The latter included as their members, in 1912, 47 per cent, of the population within their spheres of activity, a fraction which has now probably come to be more than half, whereas the funds grouped only 24 per cent, of the population within their spheres. The capital of the co-operative societies was distributed as follows : I July 1914 I January 1915 I January 1916 Capital : belonging to them- selves belonging to depo- sitors belonging to the State belonging to the Zemstvos and others Total . . . in terms of thousands of roubles [in terms of thousands of roubles % 96,687 12.5 487,508 63.0 148,159 19.2 40,808 5.3 14.0 66.6 99.501 472,862 105,218 15.0 32,464 4.4 in terms of thousands of roubles 110,078 535.372 95.509 42,900 % 154 68.6 12.3 3-7 773,162 100 710,045 ICO 783,859 100 In a certain number of districts the inflow of deposits was so great that the co-operative societies could not utihze them. Paper and specie have therefore augmented considerably, their value passing from 86,416,000 loubles to 141,416,000 roubles, that is 20 per cent of the amount on the balance-sheets. b) Purchases and sales effected by small credit establishments. Owing to present circumstances the co-operative societies are under- taking business usually outside their range of activity or only a very sub- sidiary part thereof, such as the lending of agricultural machines for the field work of their members, the lending of seed, the purchase and sale of 22 RUSSIA - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION the agricultural products and the medicinal plants of their members, and the purchase of ahmentary products where there are no co-operative con- sumers' societies or these have insufficient resources. The course of stim- ulating the activity' of consumers' co-operative societies b}" making loans to them is however preferred. Thus in May 1915 a ruling allowed co- operative credit societies to lend 1,000 roubles — or even more in case of necessity — to co-operative consumers' societies. In 1915 the following sums, expressed in terms of thousands of rou- bles, were employed on various purchases : I January i October Sums actually paid for purchases: by co-operative credit societies 7994 ^>959 )) deposit and loan funds 397 828 Total . . . 1,196.4 2,787 Products of sales : by co-operative credit societies 736 1,886 » deposit and loan funds no 647 Total ... 846 2,533 Merchandise bought • by co-operative credit societies 9.275 ^5353 » deposit and loan funds 2,683 5,480 Total . . . 11,958 20,833 The enterprises organized b}^ the co-operative societies are, besides the corn magazines, co-operative mills in Siberia near the stations of l,e- begia, Cocenovo, etc. Quite recent foundations are those of tileworks in the government of Kharkov, tanneries, factories for preserving fruit in Dage.stan province, metallurgical establishments manufacturing the re- quisites of domestic industry, experiments in realizing the value of peat, etc. c) Distribution of co-ot>e'rative societies according to regions. The following table shows the number of co-operative credit soci- eties and of savings and loan funds in each region and their financial importance on i October 1915 : POPULAR CO-OPERATIVE CREDIT 23 a Q u a t! C3 V •a •s n 29 II i lit I tors <3 iC o -3 -n 00 0 0 00 00 00 0 m ^ 00 u-i •o 0 r^ fO 00 0 0 o^ U-) 0 fO " cattle that 3^ou wish. " Q. I have the money and intend to pay cash for my stock: what advantage is there in buying through the association ? " A. The advantages to you are these: 3^ou get cheaper transporta- tion rates because the stock is shipped in car-load lots ; you also have the services of an expert judge of dairy cattle, free of charge, to assist in the selection of 5-our stock. " Q. I do not like to give a- chattel mortgage on anything : will the trustees accept my note if some responsible person would sign it with me ? " A. Yes, the trustees will accept a note if it has a good endorsement, and not require a chattel mortgage. The onh' object of the mortgage is to secure the note and protect the guarantors, as far as possible. " Q. I am anxious to raise beef cattle. Will the trustees help me to obtain them and allow time payments ? " A. No. The trustees have received their instructions to buy onh^ Guernsey and Holstein cattle, either grades or registered, and allow payment on time. " Q. I would like to pay for my cattle in payments six months apart, rather than monthly. Could that be arranged ? " A. Yes. The plan of monthly payments is not ironclad, and we will try to accommodate those who, for good reasons, desire some other method of payment. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 33 " Q. Is it alwa^-s possible to get exactly the kind of stock everyone wants ? " A. Sometimes it is very possible and in certain instances it may be impossible. Where such diiRculty is encountered the men who are buA'ing use their own best judgement and get as near as possible what the applicant desires. " O. If I do not like the stock when it arrives will I be compelled to accept it ? " A. Yes. According to the terms of the application and agreement you are bound to accept the cattle when they arrive. The trustees are your agents and you must take the stock they get for you. " Q. How much commission is charged for buying the stock? " A. None whatever. In addition to the actual cash expenses of getting the stock and delivering them, a charge of two dollars per head is made, to cover necessarj- expenses of printing, postage, interest on mo- ney used on buj'ing the cattle, etc. In time this may possibly create a small reserve that could be used to pay any losses that might occur. " Q. Isn't there a danger of tuberculosis when stock is shipped from so man^^ farms in different sections of the State ? " A. None whatever : the cattle are all tested for tuberculosis before being shipped ". The following is the form of " application for time payment " : " The undersigned hereby applies to trustees appointed by the Marinette County Advancement Association, for the loan of .... , dollars, or a sulhcient sum to purchase .... cows , . . . . heifers and one male .... j^ears old. " The breed to be ... . " The following is a true statement of the undersigned's resources and liabilities : Resources. Liabilities. Description ...... Amount owing § Acres land cleared ... To whom ? Value $ Acres partlj' cleared . . Nature of security ? Value $ Acres wild Value $ Horses and cattle, value . $ Machinery ...» $ Other resources . » $ " I. The Undersigned For Value Received, Hereby agrees to pa}'' said Trustees, or their order, on or before three 3'ears from this date, the sum required to pay the entire cost of the animal purchased by him, with interest at 6 per cent, per annum, interest payable semi-annually, such obligation to be evidenced by a promissory note to the undersigned. 34 INFORMATION REI^ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION " 2. The Undersigned Further Agrees, to pay to said Trustees or their assigns at stated intervals each month not less than .... per month for each animal so purchased by him until the aforesaid sum and interest is fully paid. "3. The Undersigned Further Agrees, to breed the cows and heifers so purchased to a registered sire of the same breed. " 4. The Undersigned Further Agrees, to secure the pa>Tnent of said sum and interest and the perfomance of this agreement, by a-promis- sory note and a chattel mortgage to said trustees upon the animals so pur- chased and the following additional security .... " 5. The Undersigned Further Agrees, To accept the animals that are purchased for and delivered to him by the trustees hereunder and pay for the same as herein provided. " . . . . Animals will be labelled at time of purchase and delivered to part}^ ordering same at point designated by trustees. Upon deHvery the purchaser shall pay to the Trustees the original cost of the animals together with the expense of purchasing and delivering of said animals . . . ". 2. NORTH CAROI^INA RURAI, BANKS. — The Country Gentleman. Philadelphia, 9 Decem- ber 1916. North CaroUna was the first state in the Union to estabhsh, by legisla- tive enactment, rural credit unions. Short-term loans are made to farmers at six per cent, interest. These rural banks are modelled on the country banks of Northern Italj^ and loans are restricted to purposes of acquiring land and making farm improvements. The initial North Carohna society was organized at lyowe's Grove, Durham Country', on 20 January. Since then six sim- ilar clubs have been created. The marketing division of the State De- partment of Agriculture controls the unions and a superintendent has been emplo3^ed as whole-time officer. A recent monthlj^ statement as to the condition of these banks makes this composite showing : membership, 252 farmers ; depositors, 38 ; pay- ments on shares, §1,763.20; deposits, $1,654.68; loans, §3,203.05; number of borrowers, 35 ; rediscounts, $1 290.00 ; cash in banks, $1,597-89 ; total resources, $4,883.70. While the chief aim of the unions is to escape paAanent of exorbitant rates of interest on loans for farm improvements, co-operative effort in other fields is encouraged. The Uowe's Grove Union reports a purchase of 114.3 tons of fertilizers for a cash payment of $3,050.02 The saving effected by the members of the union by bu3dng co-operativeh- instead of at the prevailing community prices was $667.43. Drowning Creek, another credit union, reports " the purchase of a carload of cottonseed meal co-operatively INFORaiATlON RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 35 by eight members. They got the same prices and discounts that the richest man of the biggest plantation in the State could get ". Neighbouring city banks and deposits of members are the sources of revenue of the rural banks. The union is empowered to borrow money from any source, provided such indebtedness do not exceed the capital, surplus and reserve fund. Essentially the plan is as follows : members of the society in need of financial aid make application to the finance committee, composed of farmer members. I^oans are - pledged at six per cent, interest, without commission, on property as security. Tenant farmers obtain loans on securing the indorsement of their landlords. The farmer buys his supplies for cash according to the plan of the co-operative society. Part II: Insurance and Thrift CHILE. THE FIRST THRIFT CONFERENCE AND THE SAVINGS BANKS OF CHIIvE. SOURCES : BoRROS BoRGONO (lyOuis) : I 480 15 » 330 20 r. 230 25 » 160 46 CHU^E - INSURANCE AND THRIFT When the sum corresponding to one of these five periods has been deposited the bank issues to the depositor a savings bond of 1,000 pesos, payable on the day on which it becomes due. If the depositor die before this date his heir can hold the bond for the remaining period or, if he pre- fer, can demand liquidation. In the latter case the bank will pay him the deposited sum, plus interest at the rate of 6 per cent, a year up to the daj^ of liquidation. The savings bond constituied by injeekly deposits is issued like the pre- ceding one, and is for 1000 pesos falling due after five, ten, fifteen, twenty or twenty-five years, the depositor being bound to pay the following sums half-yearly : Total payments pesos 840 700 480 400 Six months after the payment of the last weekly deposit the bank will pay the depositor the amount of his bond, that is 1000 pesos. If any person acquiring a bond of this description make his weekly deposits unpunctually he must pay interest for the period of delay at the rate of 10 per cent., and if the delay is for more than eighteen months the bank may liquidate the operation. In this case however it repays to the bearer of the bonds the sums he has deposited, plus interest at the rate of 6 per cent, up to the day of liqiiidation. If he die his heir may demand a liquidation or continue to make due payments. In either case the pro- cedure is that applied where a savings bond constituted by a single de- posit is concerned. The annuity bond produces a fixed weekly sum for five, ten, fifteen, twenty or twenty-five years, in return for the deposit of a given sum which bu3^s the bond, as is shown by the following table : B) Basis: ■ 6 ^ % annuall Falling due after Amount of weeklj' deposits 5- • . pesos 84 10. . , 35 IQ.50 15. . . 20. . . 12 25. . . 8 THE FIRST THRIFT CONFEREaCE 47 C) Basis 7 1/2 %• Number of years for which the depositor receives . the income Single Deposit made by him Half-yearly income paid to him by the bank Total sum i>aid by the bank during the stipulated period pesos pesos pesos 5 820 100 1,000 10 1,390 100 2,000 15 1,785 100 3,000 20 2,055 100 4,000 25 2,245 100 5,000 The bank begins to pay the income six months after the deposit has been made. It is, Hke the savings bond, non-transferable and exempt by law from seizure. An annuity bond can be bought so that the purchaser receives the income after a period of five, ten, fifteen, twenty or twenty-five years, instead of during one of these periods. The sum deposited of course varies considerably in each case, for it depends on the number of years which have to run before the bank has to begin to pa}* the rent and the number for which it is payable. The following table shows these variations : 48 CHILE - INSURANCE AND THRIFT D) Basis : 7 V2 % for the /ormatiun of tlie capital and 6 ^ % while the income U payable. Single initial deposit The bank after Pays each week to the purchaser of the bond For Total sum paid by the bank pesos years pesos years pesos 585 5 1 405 ID - 280 15 100 5 1,000 195 20 i 135 25 I 1,005 5 ■ ■ 695 ID 1 480 15 100 10 2,000 325 20 \ 230 25 1 1,315 5 910 10 630 ^5 , > 100 15 3,000 435 20 300 25 1.535 5 1 1,065 1 1 735 15 , 100 20 4,000 510 20 355 25 1,700 3 \ 1. 175 1 f 810 ^5 ICO 25 5,000 560 20 ' i 590 25 I THE FIRST THRIFT CONFERENCE 49 The new enterprises are seen to be exclusively enterprises of thrift aiming at no gain : the bonds representing them are based solely on com- pound interest. It is easily iiuderstood that the new services will be of especial benefit to the working classes. A savings bond of 1000 pesos, the capital of which has been constituted by weekly payments for twenty years, requires a deposit of 12 pesos every six months, and may therefore be said to be within the reach of every workman, however humble, since it involves a saving of only 0.50 peso a week. The other services organized on the basis of the research and delibe- rations of the First Thrift Conference, which will shortly become active if the3- are not so now, are : a) a system of cheques with special depositing forms ; b) special or privileged savings accounts ; c) safes , and d) the organization of a home service within the sphere of each central or branch office. The list of these services indicates their nature which has no par- ticular interest for us. They will however give a certain elasticity to the mechanism of the savings banks where the most modern banking opera- tions are concerned. We will end these brief notes with the statement that the First Thrift Conference proved by figures and data the importance of the work accom- plished by the Chilian savings banks. The figures we have reproduced show a constant and increasing rise in the curve representing the deposits received by this bank. It has been possible to utilize the savings for the increase of the wealth of the country and social progress. The workmen's dwellings, the purchase of rural properties, the formation of colonies of small proprietors, and the new services and commercial schemes show that the Chilian savings banks have left behind them their initial phase of hesit- ation and have succeeded in centralizing savings which will doubtless ser\-e as a basis to the future economic development of the country. URUGUAY. MORTGAGE INSURANCE. SOURCE : BANCO DE Seguros DEL Etado. Seguro Hipotecario. [Insurance Bank of the State. Mortgage Insurance). Impr. Juan J. Dornaleche. Montevideo, 1916. § I. Preliminary Remarks. The growing development in this country of long-term mortgage oper- ations, thanks to the facilities afforded by the Mortgage Bank of Uruguay and other similar institutions, has given birth — among other enterprises of the vState Bank of Insurance (i) — to a scheme foi insurance which aims at providing for the pa3'ment by mortgagers, in the case of their death, of the interest and the amortization quotas which they have engaged to pay. In other words an attempt has been made to find a method of avoiding that the heirs of a mortgager, generally his wife and children, be in the sad neces- sity of having to give up the property they ha\e inherited because they can- not continue to fulfil the mortgager's engagements ; of avoiding, that is, that they inherit not a property but a debt which they cannot pay. The State Bank of Insurance gave attention to the solution of this prob- lem, which froni the outset it considered to be in harmony with its mission as the chief agent of thrift in the economy and society of Uruguay, and was forced, in forming a basis for insurance of this type, to take different consi- derations into account. First such insurance should effectively correspond to the ends in view ; secondly its cariff" should be so low that the payment of the premium does not involve a sacrifice for those paying it ; thirdly the terms should be brought into line with the S3'stem of granting financial facilities otherwise followed b}^ the bank ; and fourthly the delay before ])re- miums are paid should be f.s short as possible. In order to understand the insurance of mortgage debts we will take a concrete example. A married man, twent3'-five 3'ears old, having limited pecuniarj' re- sources, buys a property worth .3,000 pesos (2) but has only 1,500 pesos at (ij For the organization and operations of the Statt Bank of Insurance, see our issue lor March 1917, page 35. (2) I peso = 4.283 s. at par. MORTGAGE INSURANCE 5 I his disposal. He mortgages the property he has bought for the remaining 1,500 pesos, the loan being repayable in thirty years. During his lifetime he paj^s the fixed annual instalments punctually, but after six A^ears he dies. In the course of his life he has amortized 130.56 pesos which is to sa}' that at his death he still owes 1369.44 pesos. Can his family still fulfil the obligation of the mortgage, namely make an an- nual payment of 123.38 pesos for the twenty-four years which have still to run before the obligation is cancelled ? There would not be this doubt if the individual in question had guarded against the eventuality of his early death b}' insuring his mortgage, in the manner which we will explain, at the same time as he mortgaged his property. The Insurance Bank would in this case have issued a pohcy by which it engaged to pay, to the heir or heirs named therein, a sum equal to that needed by the terms of the mortgage to pay the debt remaining a burden on the property from the time of the mortgager's death until the conclusion of the term of the mortgage. Further it is an essential condition of the mortgage in question that the obligation assumed by the bank remain valid in spite of any delay of the payments by the mortgager to the mortgagee, and in spite of payments in advance which he may have made or his sale of the mortgaged property. Thus the bank's engagement subsists for the period of thirty years and its effectiveness cannot in any way be lessened within this period. The insu- rance is therefore essentially a life insurance lasting for thirty years, in virtue of which — in relation to the mortgage which gave it birth ~ the bank must pay to the heirs of the insured person, if he die within the thirty years and whether or not he has repaid the mortgage del:)t or sold the pro- perty, the amount of the annual payments still pending at the time of his death. In other words if the mortgager die after six years of insurance, as we assumed previously, his heirs receive the sum of 1369.44 pesos even if he have repaid his debt or sold his propert3^ The costs accompanying this form of insurance are low, as is shown by the tariff which we give below, and they vary with the amount of the debt and the age of the borrower. In the case already cited the mortgager in order to insure his debt would have to pay one premium of 91.76 pesos or the following annual sums : ist. year 33.63 pesos 2nd " " . . . . 26.91 " 3rd. " 20.19 4th. " 1347 5th. •' 6.75 § 2. Terms of insurance. The following are the principal terms of the policy : a) This contract is in force from the time of the payment of the single premium or the first of the five annual instalments into which, if the con- tracting person wish, this single premium can be divided. 52 URUGUAY - INSURANCE AND THRIFT If the insured person die before five years have passed from the time at which the contract comes to have force, the bank will deduct, from the amount to be paid, the portion of the premium which still has to be paid before the total sum of the single premium is reached. b) Only long-term mortgages, constituted in conformity with the by-laws of the Mortgage Bank of Uruguay or other similar organizations, can be the objects of this insurance. c) If it be discovered at any time that the true age of the insured per- son is less than liis age as declared in the application wliich was the basis of his policy, and if his true age be more than fift}^ or the difference between his declared and his true age be more than five years, the insurance will be null and void and the bank will not be obliged to repay the paid premium. The insured person or his heirs nuist prove his age as often as the bank desire. d) The polic}^ makes no restrictions as to travelHng and place of re- sidence ; but the insured person must not blow up rocks, engage in mining or diving or the manufacture of inflammable or explosive substances, or make aerial ascents without first notifj^ing the bank and obtaining its consent, and causing the bank to establish that the premium i^hall still be recoverable and the policy remain in force. In default of such declara- tion, and in the case of an accident due to the causes here cited, the insu- rance will be null and void, and the insured person or his heirs will be able to claim no part of the amount of premium paid. e) ]\Iilitary service withJn the country or for its defence entails no increase of the premium ; but military service for a foreign nation annuls the insurance so that the insured person or his heirs can claim no part of the premium paid. /) In the case of suicide the insurance is annulled and the Vjank repays the premium or the annual payments it has received. ?) When the proofs of the death of the insured person have been presented and the bank has accepted them, the bank will, according to circumstances, pay or credit the sum due. h) The policy will be annulled if the contracting person omit to pay, when it falls due, any one of the annual instalments forming an integral part of the single premiimi on which the contract is based. We give below the tariff fixed by the bank for the insurance of mortgage debts : MORTGAGE INSURANCE 53 Amount of the Premium for jooo pesos insured for 30 years. Age Single premium in pesos Premiimi paid by annual instalments in pesos of debtor First Second Third Fourth Fifth Total of instalments years 25 60.17 22.42 17-94 13-46 8.98 4.50 67.30 26 6439 23.60 18.88 14.16 9-44 4.72 70.80 27 67.61 24.80 19.80 14.90 9.90 4.97 74-37 28 70.83 25-97 20.78 M-59 10.40 5-21 77-95 29 74-05 27-15 21.72 16.29 10.86 5.43 81.45 30 77.28 28.33 22.64 16.98 11.32 5-69 84.96 31 80.70 29.59 23.64 17-73 11.82 5-95 88.73 32 84.13 30.86 24-64 18.48 12.32 6.20 92.50 33 87.56 32.11 25.68 19.26 12.84 6.42 96.31 34 90.99 33-36 26.68 20.01 13-34 6.68 100.07 35 94-44 34.62 27.68 20.76 13-84 6.94 103.84 36 101.94 37-39 29.88 22.41 14.94 7-49 112. II 37 109.45 40.13 32.08 24.06 16.04 8.05 120.36 38 115.96 42.51 34-00 25-50 17.00 8.51 127.52 39 124.43 45.63 36.48 27.36 18.24 9.15 136.86 40 131.98 48.39 38.68 29.01 19.34 9.71 145-13 41 140.35 51.46 41.16 30.87 20.58 10.30 154-37 42 148.72 54-53 43.60 32.70 21.80 10.93 163.56 43 157.09 57-61 46.04 34-53 23.02 TI.55 172.55 44 165.46 60.68 48.52 36.39 24.26 12.14 181.99 45 173.85 63-75 50.91 38-22 25.48 12. 7§ 191.19 From all that has been said it is easy to understand the importance of this form of insurance to the rural population of a colonists' country like Uruguay where mortgage credit plays so large a role. Part III: Credit UNITED STATES. FEDERAL BANKS AND FINANCIAI, ORGANIZATION. OFFICIAI, SOURCES: An Act to provide for the establishment of Federal reserve banks, to furnish an elastic currency, to afford me.\ns of rediscounting commercial paper, to estab- lish a more effective supervision of banking in the united-states, and for other PURPOSES. Approved 23 December 1913. Public, N° 43, 63 D Gongiess. The Federal FarmI^oan Act. Approved 17 July 1916. Senate, Document N°. 500, 64th. Con- gress, ist session. An Act to amend certain sections of the Act entitled " Federal reserve Act " ap- proved 23 December 1913. Approved 7 September 1916. Public, No. 270, H. R. 13391, 64th Congress. Davis (Andrew Mc Failand) : The Origin of the National Banking System. National Monetary Commission. Washington. Government Printing Office. 1910. NOYES (Alexander Dana) : History of the National-Bank Cuirency, ibid. 1910. Holdsworth (John Thom) : The Fiist and Second Banks of the United States. National Monetary Commission, ibid : 1910. National Monelvry Comihssion. Special Report from the Banks of the United States, ibid. 1909. OTHER SOURCES: Sprague (O. M. W.) The Fedeial Reser\-e Banking System in Operation, The Qtiarferly Jouy- nal of Economics, Vol. XXX, N° 41, August 1916, Cambridge (Mass) U. S. A. MoiRE.\u (August e) : I850.66 to the credit of 25,645,604 depositors (deposit accounts), including $5,678,735,379-65 savings and time deposits, with 14,894,696 depositors. UNITED STATES - CREDIT shall be required within thirty days after notice from the organization committee, to subscribe to the capital stock of such Federal reserve bank in a sum equal to six per centum of the paid-up capital stock (i) and sur- plus of such bank, one sixth of the subscription to be payable on call of the organization committee or of the Federal Reserve Board, one sixth within three months and one sixth within six months thereafter, and the remainder of the subscription or any part thereof shall be subject to call when deemed necessary by the Federal Reserve Board, said payments to be in gold or gold certificates... Any national bank failing to signify its acceptance of the terms of this Act within the sixty days aforesaid shall cease to act as a reserve agent, upon thirty days' notice, to be given within the discretion of the said organization committee or of the Federal Reserve Board. Should an^^ national banking association in the United States now organized fail within one j^ear after the passage of this Act to become a member bank or fail to comply with any of the provisions of this Act applicable thereto, all of the rights, privileges and franchises of such association granted to it under the national bank Act (1863) or under the provisions of this Act shall be tliereb}^ forfeited... Should the total subscriptions b}' banks and the public to the said Federal reserve banks or any one or more of them be, in the judgement of the organization com- mittee, insufficient to provide the amount of capital required therefor, then that committee shall allot to the United States such, an amount of said stock as said committee shall determine... No Federal reserve bank shall commence business with a subscribed capital less than S4, 000, 000 ". Each Federal Reserve Bank is under the supervision and control of a board of nine directors, of whom three represent and are chosen by the stockholding banks, three must when elected be actively engaged in their district in commerce, agriculture or other industrial pursuit, and three are nominated by the Federal Reserve Board. The chairman of the board of directors is chosen by the Federal Reserve Board from the last named three, and also has the office of federal reserve agent, acting as official re- presentative of the Federal Resei-ve Board for the performance of the func- tions conferred on it b}^ the Act. Any bank incorporated by special law of any State, or organized un- der the general laws of any State or of the United States, may apply for the right to subscribe to the stock of the Federal Reserve Bank organized or to be organized within the Federal Reserve District in which it is situa- ted. If such application be eccepted the applicant bank must conform to the regulations as to reserves and capital and inspections which the Or- ganization Committee or the Federal Reserve Board establish. No bank may thus subscribe to the stock of a Federal Reserv^e bank if it have not unimpaired paid-up capital sufficient to aallow it to become a National Bank within its own locality in accordance with the law regulating such banks. When admitted it shall be subject to all laws applicable to National Banks. A dividend up to 6 per cent, on paid-up capital shares may be distrib- (i) The shares are of Sioo. FEDERAL BANKS AND FINANCIAL ORGANIZATION 63 iited to stockholders out of the net profits of the Federal Reserve Bank. Half the surplus profits shall be paid to the government of the United States and the other shall constitute a special reserve fund. When the latter has reached an amount equal to 40 per cent, of the bank's paid up capital the whole balance will return to the governement. The property of Federal Reserve Banks — including their capital shares, their reserves and all their revenue, is exempt from all taxation of the United States Government or the States or other authority, except the land tax. When the Organization Committee has accomplished its task it gives place to the Federal Reserve Board which meets in Washington and is the motive power of the whole system. It has seven members, namely the vSecretary of the Treasury and the Comptroller of the Currency who are members ex officio, and five others appointed to hold office for ten years by the President of the United States with the consent of the Senate. In appointing them the President has due regard to a fair representation of the different commercial, industrial and geographical divisions of the coun- try, and he designates one of them as governor and one as vice-governor of the Federal Reserve Board, the former being the board's active execu- tive officer. The Act also creates a Federal Advisory Council, consisting of as many members as there are Federal Reserve Districts, each Federal Reserve Bank sending a representative to it. This council meets at least four times a year : it confers directly with the Federal Reserve Board on gene- ral business conditions ; it makes oral or written representations concern- ing matters within the jurisdiction of this board ; and it calls for infor- mation and makes recommendations in regard to discount rates, rediscount business, note issues, reserve conditions in the various districts, the pur- chase and sale of gold or securities by reserve banks, open market opera- tions by these banks, and the general affairs of the reserve banking sj^stem. Previously National Banks were obliged to have a reserve equal to 25 per cent, of the amount of their deposits in the reserve towns and 15 per cent, in the other towns ; but the Act of 191 3 made this percentage 18 in New York, Chicago and St. lyouis, 15 in other reserve towns, and 12 in non- reserve towns. The excesses of available reserves should be transferred in accordance with certain conditions to the Federal Reserve Bank. For twenty years from 1915 the member banks of a Federal Reserve Bank may apply to sell "all or some of their circulating notes which they desire to retire. The Federal Reserve Board will decide on such applications. A Fede- ral Reserve Bank may not purchase more than §25,000,000 of such bonds in a year. Upon depositing with the Treasurer of the United States bonds so purchased, or any bonds with the circulating privilege acquired under this Act, any Federal Reserve Bank shall receive from the Comptroller of the Currency circulating notes in blank equal in amount to the par value of the deposited bonds. Such notes shall be issued and redeemed on the 64 UNITED STATES - CREDIT same terms and conditions as National Bank notes, except that they shall not be limited to the amount of the capital stock of the Federal Reserve Bank issuing them. Thus the circulation of notes will eventually be ap- preciably simplified and unified. The law perfects the machiner\^ for controlling the banks. In addi- tion to the inspections by the Comptroller of the Currenc}', inspections of any bank by the Federal Reserve Bank of its district can be authorized by the Federal Reserve Board. The Federal Reserve Banks are them- selves inspected annually and their member banks can obtain that they be inspected specially. As regards the special interests of agriculture — every National Bank not situated in a central reserve town may make loans on cultivated, un- mortgaged land within its district, for a term of no more than five years, of amounts not exceeding 50 per cent, of the value of the property offered as securit3^ Each of these banks may thus lend as much as 25 per cent, of its capital and reser^^es or one third of its term deposits and continue as previous^ to receive term deposits and pay interest on them. The Federal Reserve Board will have the right to add other towns from time to time to the list of those in which the National Banks may not thus grant loans secured by landed property. Federal Reserv^e Banks within the territory of the United States do no business with the public directly but only with each other and with the Na- tional Banks. Their deposits emanate only from their stockholders ' and the government of the United States. By means of the notes they issue they may rediscount the commercial paper of their respective National Banks and discount the notes and acceptances of foreign banks. They may open branches abroad which may transact all normal banking busi- ness directl}'. Both abroad and at home these banks are the government's fiscal agents, and as such recover taxes and duties, pay arrears of the pubhc debt, etc. § 4. The workixg of the federal reserve banks. As soon as the Act had been passed the organization committee got to work. Its first difficult}^ was to fix the number of the districts in which there should be banks, for the interests of the different States could not be neglected. It was decided that there should be twelve districts, and that the banks should have their sites in Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Cleve- land, Richmond, Atlanta, Chicago, St. lyOtiis, oVIinneapohs, Kansas City, Dallas and San Francisco. The notice provided by the Act was giveil to the various banks and on 18 Ma}- the decree for the organization of the Federal Reserv^e Banks was drawn up. The banks of each district were then divided into three equal groups, according to the amount of capital and property they held. At the beginning of July 1914 each group in the FEDERAI, BANKS AND FINANCIAL ORGANIZATION 65 various districts elected two directors of a Federal Reserve Bank. This somewhat complicated procedure allows the small banks to be represented on the directors' boards of their respective Federal Reserve Banks. The election ended the task of the organization Committee and on 10 August the Federal Reserve Board was sworn in. It comprises in addition to its statutory members an expert in foreign banking and investing, a Southern banker, a jurist, an economist, and a railway expert. It had first to nominate the three representatives of the government in the directors' boards of the Federal Reserve Bank. Meanwhile the interior organization of the. banks was studied by a technical committee. It was judged well to divide the powers of the boards of directors into two. The chairman, appointed by the Federal Reserve Board from the three official represen- tatives, is this board's intermediary as regards the direction and superin- tendence of the business of a bank, and the governor — whom the directors appoint from their own number — is the effective president. The direc- tors have been well chosen for their financial capabilities and have greatly ministered to the scheme's development. Each Federal Reserve Bank is largely an independent institution, managed by local persons. Its offi- cials and directors can speak with authority for the different local interests they represent. The opinions of the governors, supported by their boards of directors and amplified by the Federal Advisory Council, have had much weight in this first period of the activity of the new banking machinery. In October 1914 the work of organization was far from complete, but in view of the conditions created by the European war it was thought well not to defer the opening of the banks. The opening day was fixed for 16 November and the first payment of capital was made on i November. Of the 7,493 National Banks which were active only eighteen refused their subscription. The first contribution was slightly over $18,000,000 ; and the aggregate nominal capital was about $106,800,000, that is slightly less than $14,000 for each stockholding bank. Succeeding pa^^ments were made on i February and i May 1915. The other half of the sub- scribed capital stock will probably not be called for so soon. In June 1916 the paid-up capital amounted to $54,864,000. In addition the Federal Reserve Banks disposed on the opening day of the part of the reserves of the stockholding banks which was to be trans- ferred to them under the Act. The banks of the central reserve towns thus transferred a sum equal to 7 per cent, of the deposits they held, the banks of reserve towns made a preliminarv^ deposit of 3 per cent, and the others one of 2 per cent. (i). The Federal Reserve Banks also received at one time about $ 230,000,000, which with the first payment of capital brought their available funds up to about $ 250,000,000. These transferences were made quite easilj' and conveniently. (i) The deposits of the two lattei were completed on 16 November 191 5 and 16 May and 16 November 1916, and their transferred reserves thus came to be 6 and 5 per cent., respectively. 66 UNITED STATES - CREDIT The Act provided that the rediscount of the paper of stockholding banks should in normal times constitute a Federal Bank's chief business. The rate of such discount was first fixed at from 5 Y2, to 6 Y2 P^r cent., according to the term of the bills. But as the Act had lowered the mini- mum neces.sary reserve of the National Banks, these disposed of large sums which the}^ previously could not touch and were therefore able to extend their business without rediscounting their paper. Thus the available reserve of the National Banks of New York rose from 8 85,000,000. From being tight money became plentiful ; the Reserve Banks had to meet no demand for rediscoimt except in the three Southern districts ; and at the end of 1914 the rate was brought to 4 7^ and 5 per cent. At this time the whole rediscount business reached the sum of §10,593,000, of wliich 84,027,000 belonged to the Southern districts. The rate of rediscount was lowered to 4 per cent, in 191 5 ; and at the end of this year the whole re- discount business figured as §32,000,000, of which sum 74 per cent, belong ed to the Southern banks. On 17 June 1916 this sum had been reduced to §20,425,000, §13,307,000 belonging to the Southern banks. It is how- ever probable that when the abnormal conditions created by the war are at an end, that is when the large facilities for credit offered in consequence of the great influx of gold into the Um'ted States are no more, rediscounting by the Federal Reserve Banks will be more important. The unimportance of this branch of business is not due to the nature of the paper to be discounted. Under the Act the Reserve Banks may only rediscount bills representing loans for commercial purposes ; but the adjective is given a large interpretation, for all advances of funds repaA'able within ninetj- days, and made b}' a bank to a borrower whose current assets are in excess of liis liabilities, are considered to be com- mercial loans. Agricultural paper and bills given for loans on cattle are given a pre- ference in that they may be rediscounted even if their term be six months. A large part of the rediscounting done by the Reserve Banks has concerned paper of this description. Thus on 17 June 1916 63 per cent, of the loans granted by the Bank of Minneapolis were of this kind, as were 36 per cent, of those of the Bank of Dallas and about 2^ per cent, of those of the Banks of Kansas City and Chicago. Rediscounting is naturally active only in districts in which ordinary credit facilities do not suffice. The three Reserve Banks of the South appear consequently likeh^ to be able to emplo}- considerable sums in bu- siness of this kind. The Act supplies another means of investment to the Federal Reserve Banks. They may buy in the open market bonds of the United States, bonds of the various States and municipal bonds at six months, and also bills of exchange arising out of commercial transactions. On 17 June 1916 the}- held United States bonds for 859,000,000. Of municii:)al bonds, which are far less liquid, they then held §22,300,000 and had at an earlier date held §40,000,000. The Act authorizes them to purchase and discount bills of exchange FEDERAL BANKS AND I'lNAXCIAL ORGANIZATION 67 arising out of home trade, a form of paper which both the legislature and the Federal Reserve Board prefer unhesitatingh- to simple bills payable on order, whether these have only one signature or are endorsed by the signa- tory's bank. But since commercial acceptances of this kind are few in num- ber, business of this kind has hitherto been insignificant. Banking accep- tances have on the other hand been most important. The development of these transactions is due above all to the rapidit}' with which the Fede- ral Reserve Banks have bought such acceptances at a moderate rate. In February' 1915 the rate oscillated from 2 to 4 per cent, but most purchases were made at 2 % and 2 ^/^ per cent. They comprise a large quantity of foreign paper for which the normal market is London. At the date mention- ed their total amount was §64,953,000. All the Reserve Banks except that at Dallas had part in them ; but they were chiefly undertaken by the banks of New York, Philadelphia and Boston. On 10 November 1916 the liabilities of the Federal Banks amounted to 8650,000,000, represented as to one tenth by the paid-up capital stock and as to nine tenths by the deposits of stockholding banks. Their own bills have hitherto circulated little, circumstances not rendering them ne- cessaries. Their assets amounted to $400,000,000 in gold, 8110,000,000 in paper, a certain quantity of their bills, and accounts with neighbouring banks. The unification which the federal reserve system was designed to effect was shown first by the adoption of a method of weeklj' settlements of ac- counts among the various federal banks, the difference between the debit and credit sides of such accounts being rectified by a remitment of specie or bills. The deplacement of assets from one district to another is thus reduced to the minimum. In the second place since 15 June 1916 the re- covery without charge of cheques and bills has been enforced by the Fede- ral Reserve Board. Every stockholding bank now sends to its Reserve Bank its cheques and bills on other stockholding banks — who are bound to pay them without deduction — and also on other banks which have accepted this condition. The number of the establishments outside the sphere of the Reserve Banks which already practised this method was very considerable. This system may be considered to be almost general. A commission which strictly covers the costs is charged on each transac- tion. The procedure is expected to strengthen the banking machiner^'^ of the whole country, and to place it in this particular under the control of the Federal Reserve Banks. The attraction of the new financial organization seems not yet to have been full)- felt by the vState and other banks, of wliich onh' some ha\'e be- come stock holders of the Reserve Banks, either transforming themselves into National Banks or keeping their particular charters. It should be mentioned that most of the Federal Reserve Banks in their first ^'•ear of activity did not succeed in realizing sufficient profits to cover their co.sts and distribute the anticii)ated dividend of 6 per cent. ; but these initial difficulties are disappearing. 68 UN^ITED STATES - CREDIT § 5. Modifications under the act of 1916. On the seventh of last December Congress passed an Act modifying that of igi6 in several respects with a view to ampUfying its scope. Certain of these modifications were proposed by the Federal Reserve Board in its last report. The innovations aimed at making the federal reserve system more attractive, that is to say more profitable, to the stockholding banks, and at extending the scope and usefulness of the Federal Reserve Banks. In abolishing restrictions on the acceptance by stockholding banks of bills of exchange of home origin which are sufficiently guaranteed the Act has placed within their reach a considerable source of profit, and has at the same time provided a new means of credit to the agricultural, indus- trial and commercial world ; for notes, drafts and bills of exchange secured by agricultural products and other goods and merchandise can be thus discounted. Agricultural paper maturing in six months at most ma}' be discounted up to an amount equivalent to a percentage of the Federal Bank's assets determined by the Federal Reserve Board. Banks in districts having no more than 5,000 inhabitants are authoriz- ed to act as agents of insurance companies and agents for transactions of land credit, and are thus enabled to undertake two kinds of lucrative business. As regards land credit, the article of the earlier Act to which we have referred is modified as follows : " Any national banking association not situated in a central reserve city may make loans secured by improved and unencumbered farm land situated within its Federal reserv^e district or within a radius of one hundred miles of the place in which such bank is located, irrespective of district lines, and may also make loans secured by improved and unencumbered real estate within one hundred miles of the place in which such bank is located, irrespective of district lines ; but no loan made upon the security of such farm land shall be made for a longer time than five A^ears, and no loan made upon the security of such real estate as distinguished from farm land f.hall be made for a longer time than one year, nor shall the amount of any such loan, whether upon such farm land or upon such reale estate, exceed fifty per centum of the actual value of the property offered as security. Any such bank may make such loans, whether secured by such farm land or such real estate, in an aggre- gate sum equal to twenty-five per centum of its capital and surplus or to one third of its time deposits and such banks may continue hereafter as heretofore to receive time deposits and to pay interest on the same". • The Act increases the power of the Federal Reserve Banks in that it allows the Federal Reserve Board to authorize " member banks to carry in the Federal reserve banks of their respective districts any portion of the reserves " previously required to be held in their own vaults ; and in that it increases the faciUties of member banks for short term credit, secur- ed by bills not actually discounted. Anj- national banking association FEDERAL BANKS AND FINANCIAL ORGANIZATION 69 may apply to the Federal Reserve Board for permission " to establish branches in foreign countries or dependencies or insular possessions of the United States for the furtherance of the foreign commerce of the United States and to act if required to do so as fiscal agents of the United States ". Owing to the initial deposit of the reserves of member banks and the transfer allowed by this Act the Federal Banks now hold about a quarter of the country's grand stock of gold. * * * Such is in outHne the financial and banking sstem instituted in 1913 and revised in 1916. It is seen to have involved no radical upheaval of the previous organization. It merely added some new wheels which centra- hzed, and in some respects gave a new direction to, the complex and some- what unequal mechanism constructed since the beginning of the repubUc. The State Banks, the National Banks, the sub-treasuries, the circulation emanating from banks in direct contact with the people and secured by Federal debt bonds, were not abolished. They subsist. But the concen- tration of a considerable part of the national gold reserves in a small num- ber of Federal banks, which could issue Federal notes in case of need, makes incontestably a regularizing force in the money market, and will probably ensure the normal course of commercial and banking operations in times of crisis. This centralizing tendency is equally appHed to agriculture by the Act of 17 Jidy 1916 on agricultural credit. Under this Act also the territory is divided into twelve districts, in this case in accordance with the needs of the different districts for agricultural credit. A Federal land bank is instituted in each of these districts and may open branches within their respective limits. The Federal land banks are individually ruled by ad- ministrative boards and collectively by a Federal board of agricultural credit. The minimum subscribed capital — $4,000,000 in the case of Federal Reserve Banks — is $750,000 in the case of Federal banks of agri- cultural credit ; and as the former receive it from the National Banks so do the latter receive it from national associations of agricultural credit, the government of the United States supplying any deficiency in the case of both. Banks of both categories act as fiscal agents of the government and receive deposits of public funds. Ever>^ Federal Reserve bank can buy and sell land bonds issued in accordance with the agricultural credit Act, .exactl> as they can under- take analogous operations involving district, county and municipal bonds. Federal land banks are inspected according to the rules applicable to National and to Federal Reserve Banks. MISCElvIvANEOUS INFORI\IATION REI^ATING TO CREDIT IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. CANADA. THE APPIvICATION OF THE AGRICUI^TURAI, ACT IN BRITISH COIyUlVIBIA. — The Hon. Wm. Manson, superintendent of the Agricultural Credit Commission of British Co- lumbia in The Agricultural Journal, Victoria 'British Columbia), Vol. I. No. g, November 1916. The Agricultural Act was placed upon the Statute Book of British Columbia in March 1915. It authorizes the borrowing of .$15,000,000 to be administered b}^ a Commission, the debentures of this Commission being guaranteed by the government of the province. The money market has been unfavourable to borrowing money for some time before and since the oubreak of the war, but last spring a loan of S 1,000,000 was obtained under the Act to begin the work and give definite aid in developing agriculture. The monej'^ cost 5.63 percent, and is being lent to the farmers at 6 14 P^r cent. Long term loans for twenty, thirty and thirtj^-six and a half years ma}' be made on the amortization plan, interest and principal being pay- able half-yearly. Short term loans for from three to ten years need not be amortizable. The Commission has decided that, while it prefers all such loans to be amor- tizable, it will yet for the present grant straight loans for three, four or five 3'^ears, the interest on which will be payable half-3'early ; and that loans for from six to ten years must, like the long term loans, be payable on the instalment plan, the interest and principal being payable half-yearly. Borrowers may from time to time, on any date at which interest is due, pay off % 25 or any multiple of $ 25 in addition to the regular half- yearly payments. The Act requires that money lent for the improvement of agricultural land be advanced only as such improvements are made, and the Com- mission is arranging accordingly in granting each loan. A great manj^ applications are being received for money to pay off existing mortgages. In view of the limited amount of money at its dispo- INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT 71 sal it is the policy of the Commission to give first consideration to applica- tions for money to be used towards the definite increase of agricultural production. The applications for money to be used exclusively to pay oft" mortgages are therefore being held abeyant for the time being. As the system is still new in British Columbia statistical information is limited^ but the following figures may be of interest. Applications received to date » appraised ■ » » Loans granted » » Applications withdrawn » » » refused » » )) held over » » (for mone}' to pay off existing mortgages) Number Average Amount Total Amount . . 104 $ 1,554 $ 2,175,443 . . 464 )) 2,324 » 1,078,606 • . 144 » 1,628 » 234,430 • • 7 » 2,368 -£6,575 . . 142 » 2,425 » 344.405 . . — — --" 121 » 3.078 372.450 Loans Granted. 5 of 2 » 21 » 2 » 3 )) 2 )) 2 » ; 26 » 4 » ' 12 » I )) 16 » 4 » 16 » I )) 8 » 4 » 2 )) 4 » I )) 6 » I » I » 144 250 __ c 1,250 300 = 600 500 = 10,500 600 = 1,200 750 = 2,250 800 = 1,600 850 = 1,700 1,000 = 26,000 1,200 = 4,800 1,250 = 15,000 1,300 = 1,300 1,500 = 24,000 1,800 = 7,200 2,000 = 32,000 2,280 = 2,280 2,500 = 20,000 3,000 = 12,000 3,500 = 7,000 4,000 = 16,000 4.250 = 4.250 5,000 = 30,000 5.500 = 5.500 8,000 = 8,000 $ 234,430 72 INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT The terms for which loans have been granted are as follows ; 3 years, straight loans 3 5 » » » 28 7 » amortizable » i 8 » » » 3 9 » » » I ID » » » 42 20 )) » » 32 30 » » » 14 36 ^ » » » 20 Total ... 144 Appraisal Fees. S 500 or under Over S 500 up to 8 1,250. . .' )) S 1,250 » » S 2,500. . . » S 2,500 » 1) S 10,000. . . Legal Fees. Up to S 2,500 Over S 2,500 up to .S 3,750. . . >' S 3,750 » )) 8 5,000. .■ . » 8 5,000 » » S 7,500. . . » S 7.500 )) » 8 10,000. . . 2.50 5.00 750 10.00 5.00 7-50 10.00 15.00 20.00 Half yearly repayments on loans are as follows, interest and principal being included : On 8 1,000 for 3 years S 186.00 4 » 145.00 5 )) 119.00 6 » 102.00 7 8 )) M 90.25 81.25 9 10 » » 74-25 69.00 20 30 36 1/2 » » 45.00 38.25 36.00 The Commission was employing last November five appraisers in different parts of the province and every effort was being made to complete the work of appraising before the winter weather set in. IXFORMATIOX REI,ATING TO CREDIT 73 Two of the directors of the board have spent a considerable time in the field with the appraisers, in order to obtain first-hand information as to agricultural land and conditions throughout the province and to help them to establish a proper basis of valuation. The reports of the appraisers are received at the head office weekly, and as they come in the Commission decides on the applications. EGYPT. THE OPERATIONS OF THE lyAND BANK OF EGYPT IN 191 6. — From the reports of the board of directors and of the auditors for 1915-1916. Alexandria, Societede publications egyptienncs 19 16. The improvement in financial conditions apparent in Egypt as early as the autumn of 1915 persisted throughout 1915-1916, important supple- mentar}' resources, determined by the European conflict, compensating partially for the deficit due to the insufficiency of the cotton harvest. This general situation influenced the business of the Land Bank of Eg3'pt in the year which closed on 30 September 1916. Mortage business, which had been arrested since the beginning of the war, consisted principally in transactions tending to consolidate and regularize certain old loans. However towards the end of the year the bank thought it right to resume on a very modest and prudent scale the examination of certain business which presented particularly advantageous conditions in the matter of security. The total sum of the mortgage loans in being on the date mentioned was 91,643,830 francs (i). Since the Eand Bank was founded it has concluded 2,552 amortizable loans and 99 sales of real estate, also amortizable, for the total sum of 195,723,088 francs. Only 26 of these loans were made last year, their total sum being 15,978,528 francs, to which a current mprtgage account of 77,770 francs must be added. Advances for short terms made last year to borrowers on mortages, who applied for them for the needs of their holdings, such loans being with- in the limits of the returns from the land cultivated, amounted to 476,332 francs. Although receipts in coin were far larger than in the preceding year, the restrictions of credit which circumstances imposed on the fellah, and the necessity of meeting none the less, with a defective production, agricultural costs increased by costliness of primary materials, increased arrears which passed from 10,486,893 francs on 30 September 1915 to 11,621,890 francs on 30 September 1916. (1)1 franc =a (j^/^d at par. 74 INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT The liquidation of real estate forming the bank's propert}* was, like annual payments, affected by events. This property comprised when the preceding banking-3-ear ended about 2,842 feddans (i) and 31,980 square pikes (2) of building land (two urban real estate holdings and fifty-three rural holdings), representing altogether a credit of '3,757,116 francs. Last 3-ear new expropriations added to this propert}' fort^^-nine rural and one urban real estate holdings, representing a credit of 3,154,535 francs. When the amount covered by the sales (twenty entire holdings, eleven parts of holdings and one urban holding), 1,527,861 francs, had been deducted there remained on 30 September igi6 two urban and 82 rural holdings having a total area of 3,813 feddans and 132,136 square pikes and representing a credit of 5,383,790 francs. The administration resulted in a total profit of 1,820,768 francs. The following tables show the nature and the terms of the loans granted : Classification of Citrrent Loans according to the Nature of the Security (30 September 191 6). Nature of loan Number Capital still due Rural loans 1,678 47 4 Egyptian pounds (i) 3,393.536 110,616 Urban » Mixed » 31,008 Total . . . 1.729 3.535,160 (i) Egyptian pound = £1.828. Thus according to these figures the rural loans represent about 97 per cent, of the total amount of the mortgage loans of the Land Bank. Classificaiion of Amortizahle Loans according to their term. Term Number of loans Capital still due lycss than 10 years, from 10 to 20 » . from 21 to 30 » from 31 to 40 n . from 41 to 50 « . Total Egyptian pounds 92 77.917-797 983 982,515.012 608 1,386,640.147 16 592,130.294 I 359,244.493 1,700 3,398,447.743 The average term of the loans is twentj'-three years and two months. (i) I feddan = 1.79374 acres. (2) I square pike = 1.67153 square yards. INFORMATION REI.ATING TO CREDIT 75 UNITED STATES. I. DETHRISIINATION OF FEDERAI^ I,AND BANK DISTRICTS. On 27 December 1916 the Federal Farm lyoan Board, created under the Federal Farm lyoan Act, announced its determinations as to the States to be included in each of the twelve Federal Land Bank Districts provided b}- the Act, and the town chosen as the site of the Dand Bank in each dis- trict. The following list shows these conclusions. District No. 1. — Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut, New York and New Jersey. The bank to be at Springfield, Massachusetts. District N° 2. — Pennsylvania, Delaware, Maryland, Virginia, West Virginia and district of Columbia. The bank to be at Baltimore, Maryland. District N^. 3. — North and South Carolina, Georgia and Florida. The bank to be at Columbia, South Carolina. District N° 4. — Ohio, Indiana, Kentucky and Tennessee. The bank to be at Louisville, Kentucky. District A^o 5. — Alabama, Mississipi and Louisiana. The bank to be at New Orleans, lyouisiana. District N° 6. — Illinois, Missouri and Arkansas. The bank to be at St. Lotus, Missouri. District A^o 7. — Michigan, Wisconsin, Minnesota and North Dakota. The bank to be at St. Paul, Minnesota. District N^ 8. — Iowa, Nebraska, South Dakota and Wyoming. The bank to be at Omaha, Nebraska. District N° 9. — Oklahoma, Kansas, Colorado and New Mexico. The bank to be at Wicliita, Kansas. District A" 10. — Texas. The bank to be at Houston, Texas. District N° 11. — California, Nevada, Utah and Arizona. The bank to be at Berkeley, California. District N° 12. -- Washington, Oregon, Montana and Idaho. The bank to be at Spokane, Washington. To this list the board added the following statement : " In determining the Federal I^and Bank Districts, and in designating the cities within such districts where Federal Land Banks shall be located, the Federal Farm Loan Board has given careful consideration to the farm loan needs of the country. The board held public hearings in nearly ever}'- State in the L'nion, and in this manner collected information of great value in determining its decision. " Ever}- reasonable opportunity has been afforded applicant cities to furnish evidence to sujjport their claim as locations of Federal Land Banks. More than seventy-five cities applied to be designated as the head quarters of a bank and were heard through representative committees and individuals ". 76 INFORMATION RELATING TO CREDIT Officials of the Farm lyoan Boards announce that before the end of 1916 more than 50,000 farmers had applied for mortgage loans, of which the approximate aggregate amount was S 150,000,000 or more than seventeen times the sum which would be immediately available for loans when the twelve farm loan banks were organized. Most of the applications came from the south and west, 2,000 of them from Iowa alone. It was expected that almost immediately after their organization the banks would find it necessary to issue bonds virtually for their entire capi- tal stock, in order to meet the demands of borrowers. 2.^THE SUBSCRIPTION OF THE CAPITAIv OF THE FEDERAL LAND BANKS. — The Economic World, New York, 10 March 1917. In accordance with the terms of the Federal Farm Loan Act subscrip- tion books were opened to the public to the capital stock of the Federal Land Banks, which are to represent in the new Federal Farm Loan System that for which the Federal Reser^^e Banks stand in the Federal Reserve System. The fact that the banks were unlikely to pay an}- dividends on this stock during the first year and that it will ultimately be retired at par naturally made it unattractive to investors. Subsciiption in none of the twelve districts nearly reached §750,000, the minimum issue of capital stock of each bank under the terms of the Act. The total sum subscribed was onl}- S 120,095, distributed as follows : Springfield, Mass.. § 10,275 '> Baltimore, Md., $9,780; Columbia, S. C, S410; Louisville, Ky., $7,735; New Orleans, La., $4,570; St. Louis, Mo., $ 7,925 ; St. Paul, Minn., $5,360; Omaha, Neb., | 41,735 ; Wichita, Kan., $ 6,335 ; Houston, Tex., $ 14,715 ; Berkeley, Cal., $ 6,110; Spokane, Wash., S 5MS- The Treasur}^ Department has therefore been obliged to subscribe no less than $8,879,905 of the capital stock of the twelve Land Banks. It is of course expected that the stock now subscribed for will be gradually retired, through the operation of the provision of the Act which requires the Farm Loan Associations — that is in the last resort the borrowing farmers themselves — to subscribe for stock of the banks to the extent of 5 per cent, of the amount they apply for as loans. The fact that legislation is now pending which will make farm loan bonds legal investments for trust fxmds and the funds of savings banks and insurance companies in most States in which they are not such already, should insure for them a ready market at a satisfactory' rate of interest. Part IV: Agricultural Economy in General GERMANY. THE SUBDIVIvSION OF I,AND IN OIvD BAVARIA. OFFICIAL SOURCE : Beitrage zu Statistik des K5NIGREICHS Bayern. I^anchvirtschaftliche Betriebsstatistik Bd. 51, 64, 81. Giiterzertrummeningen Bd. 59. Anhang 66 [Contributions to the Statistics of the Kingdom of Bavaria. The Statistics of Farms. The Subdivision of Lands). OTHER SOURCES : Rabel (Dr. B.) lyandwirtschaftlidie Besitzverteilung und Besitzverschiebuiig in Altbayem {The Distribtition and Conveyance of Farms in old Bavaria) I^eipzig, 191 5. Stechele (Dr. F.) : Die Giiterzertriiminerung und landwirtschaftliche Zwangsveraussungen in Bayern {The Distribution of Lands and Forced Transference of Landed Property in Bavaria) Annalen des Deutschen Reichs, Nos. 10-12, 1915. The name " Old Bavaria " is given to the three Bavarian provinces of Oberbayern, Niederbayern and Oberpfalz, of which the area and popula- tion are as follows : Area in Hectares (i) Number of Inhabitants Oberbayern . 1,704,653 1,434,792 Niederbayern 1,076,756 702,450 Oberpfalz 966,476 577,912 3,747,885 2,715,154 Agriculture employs the greater part of the population namely : in Oberbayern 62.7 per cent. " Niederbayern .... 65.6 " Oberpfalz 59.7 " " (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. GERMANY AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL The cultivated area measured in 1910 2,119,677 hectares, when there were 248,054 farms, which is to vSay that the average area of a farm was 8.5 hectares. Most farms measure from two to twenty hectares, and farms of this size occupy the largest part, of the cultivated area, as follows : Percentage Percentage of Number of Cultivated of Farms Area Oberbayern 62.9 51.6 Niedcrbayern 62.7 56.2 Oberpfalz 64.8 62 The group occupying the second largest part of the. cultivated area is that of the farms of from twenty to a hundred hectares : Percentage of Number of Farms Percentage of Cultivated Area I3-I 45 10.5 40.7 8.9 33-3 Oberbayern Niederbayern Oberpfalz Farms of less than two or more than a hundred hectares cover an insignificant area, but the number of those measuring less than two hectares is very large. Percentage Percentage of Number of Farms of Cultivated Area Less More Less More than 2 hectares than 200 hectares than 2 hectares than 200 hectares Oberbayern . . 23.7 0.3 1.8 1.6 Niederbayern . 26.6 0.2 2.7 1.3 Oberpfalz . . . 26.1 0.2 2.7 2 From 1882 to 1907 there were very important changes in the various groups as regards the cultivated area, the number of farms and these percen- tages. The number of the farms and the cultivated area at these two dates were as follows : 1882 1907 Number Area Niunber Area of in of in Farms Hectares Farms Hectares Oberbayern 98,296 913,116 92,243 904,227 Niederbayern ..... 83,891 687,131 82,520 680,218 Oberpfalz 65,867 519,380 64,071 494,929 THE SUBDIVISION OF LAND IN OLD BAVARIA 79 As is seen from this table both the number of farms and the ciiltiva- ted area were diminishing, doubtless as a result of the development of in- dustry. In the same period the percentage of farms having an area of from two to twenty hectares changed as follows : 1882 1907 Percentage Percentage Farms Area F, rms Area Oberbayern . 58.2 49.8 62.9 51.6 Niederbayern 57.1 52.1 62.7 56.2 Oberpfalz 59.0 55.8 64.8 62.0 This is to say that the percentage formed both by the number of these farms and by their area had increased, while these percentages concerned with farms of less than two and of more than twenty acres had decreased, as is seen from the following table : 1882 1907 Percentage Percentage Number Nimiber -rA e J 1 1 j_ of Farms Area of Farms Area Farms oi more than 20 hectares _ _ _ _ Oberbaj^ern 13.2 48.1 13.4 46.6 Niederbayern 11.2 44.8 10.7 41. 1 Oberpfalz " . . lO.i 40.8 9.1 35.3 Farms of less than 2 hectares Oberbayern 28.6 2.1 23.7 1.8 Niederbayern 31.7 3.1 26.6 2,7 Oberpfalz 30.9 3.4 26.1 2.7 The average extent has remained almost unchanged, as follows : 1882 1907 Percentage Percentage Oberbayern 9.3 9.8 Niederbayern 8.2 8.2 Oberpfalz 7.9 7.7 The official statistics give us no data as to landed property. With respect to it particular statistics, concerned only with isolated districts, must be consulted. From these we can deduce : i) That the farms having an area of from two to a hundred hec- tares are cultivated b}^ their owners, those held and cultivated by lessees representing only from 1.7 to 3 per cent, of the cultivated area. 2) That this percentage is slightly higher in the cases of farms of less than two and more than a hundred hectares. From about 15 to 20 per cent, of the total area of these groups is cultivated by lessees. The extent of the farms has been influenced by : i) the system of hereditary succession ; 8o GERMANY - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 2) the sale of property in parcels which produces excessive subdivi- sion {Guterzertriimmenrng). In all old Bavaria the system of single succession is in force. I^anded propert}^ is inherited by a single heir, the other heirs being paid the price of their shares. This S3^ste^l has a feudal origin and has been preserved by the conservative spirit of the agriculturists who have remained faithful to ancient customs. Landed property is generally, or at least oftenest, inherited by the youngest heir, for reasons both economic and social. It is the custom for chil- dren when they marry to leave the paternal home in order to settle on their own farms. A farmer generall}^ marries when he is between twenty and twenty-five years old ; and when his children marry in their turn he is still able to cultivate his farm without them. The price which the heirs receive as their share is always a little less than it would be if the land were sold freely. The price of buying back the shares is none the less very high, so that the net profit yielded by the farm is brought only with difficulty up to 2 or 3 per cent. Besides pajdng the shares of his brothers and sisters the heir of the land has to maintain his parents. The conditions of this maintenance are fixed by a contract in which the quantit}^ and quaHty of the objects agreed upon are minutel}^ specified. The stipulation that the value of the maintenance be paid in cash is very rare. This system of succession prevents the formation of too minute hold- ings, but it leaves the holdings burdened with debts ; and the eventual result of this is that there is after all subdivision. In other words holdings are sold in parcels. These sales are made : a) By the owner who retains his dwelhng-house and the appurte- nant lands and divides his remaining land into parcels which he sells se- parately. b) By the medium of a speculator in land wdio bu3''s the whole hold- ing and divides it into lots which he sells on his owai account. ,Such division has attained to enormous proportions of recent years, as is seen from the following table : 1901-1902 1902-1903 1903-1904 1904-1905 1905-1906 1906-1907 1907-1908 1908-1909 1909-1910 Properties so'ds in lots Number Area 425 8,411.77 425 8,824.85 519 11,049.23 589 11,500.44 7OQ 14,019.19 759 14.911-55 802 16,035.42 802 14,461.64 810 12,914.68 hectares THE SUBDIVISION OF LAND IN OLD BAVARIA In 1903 a commission was nominated to investigate the causes of this phenomenon and its consequences. The commission's report states that : I. The following are the causes of the excessive subdivision : 1. The debt burdening landed property, owing to the S3^stem of succession and that of subdividing the lands, that is to say to the high price which the farmer pays for the parcels he buys. 2. The insufficiency of labour which makes the costs of agriculture heavy, especially in the case of the larger farms having an area of more than twenty hectares. 3. The speculation of those who increase their profits by subdividing the lands. II. The following are the consequences of the excessive subdivision : T. The wasting of woods, for speculators in land cut down the woods on a holding before they sell it in parcels. 2. The withdrawal from agriculture of the circulating capital repre- sented by the profits of speculators which attained to nearly four and. a half million pounds in the period between 1892 and 1904. These consequences of subdivision, so detrimental to agriculture, in- duced the Bavarian government to take measures to prevent or at least to impede its progress. The first of these measures dates from about 1850 when a law forbidding subdivision by speculators was promulgated. It was however only in force for some years, being repealed about i860, between which date and 1894 subdivision was again unhampered. The measures taken by the government in 1894 and 1899 allow subdi- vision but regulate it. Special laws forbid the sale of immature woods and make the .speculator liable for arrears of taxes with which the subdivided lands ma3^ be burdened. The commission in 1903 was instructed not only to examine the caiises and consequences of subdividion but also to answer the two following questions : 1. W^ould it be opportune to forbid subdivision by decree, as was done in Wurtemberg ? 2. Would it be opportune to offer special privileges to rural banks as inducements to them to substitute themselves for speculators in land ? The commission in its report answered the first question in the nega- tive, the second in the affirmative. On the basis of this report the law on the subdivision of lands was pro- mulgated on 13 August 1910. Its most important provisions are contain- ed in its first and second articles. The fir.st article establishes a right of pre-emption in favour of : a) Rural banks of the district. b) Credit institutions authorized to such end by the Minister of Agri- culture (the co-operative agriculttiral unions having their headquarters at Munich and Regensburg have also been thus authorized). c) The respective communes. In order that this right of pre-emption may be valid it must be declar- ed within twenty-one days. 82 GERMANY - AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL, The second article gives a right to withdraw : a) to the farmer who sells his land to a speculator, within seven days ; b) to farmers buying parcels of land from speculators, within five days. The official statistics give us the following data as to the subdivision of land from I March 191 1 to the end of 1912 : 1911 1912 umber Area of subdivided properties 295 4.861.36 hectares 453 5.184.97 " If these data be compared with those for preceding j^ears the law will be seen to have lessened subdividion. The following figures show the participation of rural banks in these transactions from 1905 to 1912 : Number Area of subdivided properties 1905-1906 25 361.70 hectares 1906-1907 25 41747 1907-1908 27 312.92 1908-1909 26 344.22 1909-1910 33 430-99 1910-1911 (i) 51 953-58 1911 (2) '74 1,652.96 1912 106 ^,577-87 As is seen from this table the participation of rural banks has notice- ably increased since the law of 13 August 1910 has been enforced, while that of speculators has diminished. The following figures show the part played by speculators in the aggregate subdivision accomplished in 1912. Oberbayem 24.2 per cent. Niederbayern 46.2 Oberpfalz . 49.1 (i) Up to I March. (2) From I March. THE SUBDIVISION OF I^AND IN OLD BAVARIA 83 In spite of the favourable results obtained in 1911 and 1912 those who understand the question do not anticipate that the rural banks will com- pletely supersede the speculators. Subdivision does not entirely square with the business of rural banks. It is a transaction which needs large ca- pital and time for its conclusion ; and if is moreover an entirely commer- cial transaction which cannot be free from a speculative element. There- fore it is somewhat outside the scope of the rural banks ; and the found- ation of special institutions which will undertake it has been proposed. AUSTRIA. SOME AGRTCULTURAIv PROBI^EMS IN DALMATIA. OFFICIAI, SOURCE. OE3TERREICHI3CHES Jahrbuch FUR 1912 (AustHan Yearbook for 1912), Vienna 1912. OTHER SOURCES : GrubisiC (A.) : Agranie operazije kas sredstvo za podigxince ekonomi&ik okolnosti Dalmacije [Agricultural Operations as a means of promoting Economic Progress in Dalmatia), I'ola, 1911. ViNSKA Kriza. IzvesCe o ankeli [The Crisis in Wine Production. Reports of the Enquiry) Spa- lato, 1909. lyElTHE (Dr. H.) : Dalmatinische Agrarprobleme [Dahnatian Agrarian Problems), Wrena, 1912. § I. Agricultural area and umprovements. Dalmatia is pre-eniinently au agricultural country\ According to the available statistics it had, in 1911, 642,810 inhabitants of whom 518,790 or 86 per cent, belonged to the agricultural 'class. Nevertheless Dalmatia exports no agricultural products, but in fact imports a large quan- tity of them. In 1912 it imported : 240,500 crowns' (i) worth of cereals 797,300 " " fruit and vegetables 293,200 " " " animal products. The values of the merchandise of these respective categories exported were 69,400, 133,100 and 81,900 crowns. Onl}' with respect to Uve stock did the value of exports — 674,000 crowns — exceed that of imports — 26,800 crowns. Thus the case of Dalmatia is the singular one of an agricultural country which has an agricultural production inadequate to its own needs. It is worth while to seek the causes of this phenomenon. (i) I crown of gold =10 — d. at par. 12 SOME AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS IN DALMATIA (S5 Dalmatia has an area of 1,283,000 hectares (2) distributed as follows Arable land 137,238 hectares Vineyards 81,853 Olive plantations .' . . . 31,992 Gardens 37.024 Prairie-land 10,492 Pasturage • 562,900 Woods 329,627 Marshy lands 63,383 Roads, water-courses, buildings, etCi . . . 29,000 The terms pasturage and woods need explanation. The official statistics include as woods all lands once wooded, even in a somewhat remote past and even if to-day they are bare save for occasional shrubs and bushes. The name pasturage is applied even to lands on wliich grass grows sparsely for three or four months of the year while for eight or nine months the}' are completely bare. The table we have given shows that 22 per cent, of the whole area is cultivated while 78 per cent, is formed of uncultivated land. With respect to the soil's natural fertility the total area of Dalmatia can be divided into land of three categories : 1. The land of the first category has an area of from 180,000 to 200,000 hectares. It comprises the so-called " polja " strips of land b'ing along the shores and the banks of the water-courses. This land is excep- tionally fertile. 2. The second category includes all the woodland and most of the pastureland and may be considered to have a minimum fertility. 3. Between these two extremes is a third category, that of the marshy lands and the mountain slopes. In point of natural fertility these lands ap- proximate to those of the first category. But before they can be brought under cultivation preliminary measures are necessary — the draining of the marshy lands and the reforestation of the mountain lands. Without these improvements these lands approximate rather to those of the second cate- gory, remaining lands of minimum fertility. The facts stated point to the first agricultural problem which has to be solved in Dalmatia, that namely of extending the cultivated area. For this improvements of two kinds are needed — works of drainage and of reforestation. § 2. The distribution^ of landed property. With respect to the distribution of landed property Dalmatia presents two extremes : properties are very large or very small. This is due to spe- (2) I hectare = 2.47 acres. 86 AUSTRIA - AGRICULTRAI. ECOXOMY IX GEXER.^L cial conditions in the country. The feudal regime estabhshed under the influence of Venetian dominion, Turkish dominion and Slav customs has been preserv^ed until to-da^^ The large properties belong todndividuals or to the communes, the latter owning altogether 656,000 hectares or 50 per cent, of the countr>^'s whole area. Side by side with the large properties, which are an outcome of the feudal system, properties of very small extent have gradually been formed as follows : a) By means of contracts of sale and purchase. The large landowners are not averse from selling their property, for in Dalmatia there is almost always a lack of labour and very extensive areas are therefore left uncultiv- ated. b) By means of a distribution among members of a commune of the comnmnal landed property. Hitherto about 12,000 hectares have thus been distributed. c) By means of encroachments on the communal property. Large and small properties are alike often scattered. Small proprie- tors generally own from three to four quarter or half-hectare plots. Large proprietors often possess fifty scattered parcels of land, sometimes even more. Among the reasons for this state of affairs are the unequal fertility of the lands, the distribution caused b}^ inheritance and the encroachments. A small proprietor himself cultivates and realizes the value of his land ; whereas a large proprietor nearly always lets it. The latter himself cul- tivates it and realizes its value only exceptionally, most frequently in the south of Dalmatia, in the province of KanaH where there is an abundant supply of Montenegrin labour. Large properties are alwa3"S let in parcels. There are two forms of leases ; a) the ordinary lease which is very rare ; and b) the contract of cul- tivation, a type to which from 85 to 90 per cent, of the contracts conform. Parcels let b^^ these contracts have an area of from one to three hectares. The communes, especially those in the northern islands, also let the arable lands which form part of their landed propert3^ Their woods and pasturelands are used by all their members. Owing to the lack of labour consequent on the emigrations of recent years an important amount of land admitting of citltivation is lying fal- low. The distribution of landed property, as this has been explained, and the method by which it is cultivated, bring us to three further agrarian problems : those nameh', of i) the farming contract, 2) the distribution of communal landed property, and 3) the redivision of lands. SOME AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS IX DALMATIA 87 § 3. The FARMING CONTRACT. This contract is from a legal point of view a lease sui generis, whereas from an economic point of view it ma^^ be regarded as imposing a sUghtly modified feudal tenure. Its content is as follows : 1. The proprietor lets to the cultivator the land when it is still hdng waste. The cultivator must therefore bring it under cultivation before he can farm it. 2. The duration of the contract depends on the duration of crops. Where grain is grown it is from one to two years, in the case of vineyards from twenty-five to fifty years. 3. The contract obliges the lessee to give a part of the gross products, generally a quarter, to the proprietor. Such is the content of the normal and most usual type of contract. Exceptionally there aie deviations from it as regards the duration of the lease and its terms. The most important results of such contracts are : a) Extensive agriculture. b) Difficulties, unfortunateh^ too frequent, arising between the pro- prittor and the lessee. Since the lessee is obliged to render a share of the gross products to the proprietor, he does no more than cultivate the land on the extensive system, for otherwise he would have to give the proprietor all or almost all its net 3'ield owing to the law as to a rental which is less than proportionate. Extensive agriculture is facilitated by the fact that the lessee is as a rule himself a small proprietor. It is therefore entirely to his interest to culti- vate his own property first, and the land he rents is in consequence often not cultivated in time. The lessee looks upon the proprietor as a parasite who steals from him a part of liis products. He therefore seeks by every means in his power to take back what he considers to have been robbed from him. About 1894 an event occurred which resulted in the supersession of a fair number of farming contracts by ordinars' leases. Towards 1890 the phylloxera appeared in the countr5^ Gradually the vineyards of Dalmatia were devastated. Tliis fact in itself annulled the contracts relevant to them. Everywhere people began to replace the indi- genous vine with the American variety. Plantation however necessitated larger expenditure. Contracts of lease are more easily adapted than farming contracts to plantations of this kind ; and so it came about that a misfortune produced good results. The farming contracts were reduced by 20 per cent. AUSTRIV - AGRICUIvTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL § 4. Distribution of communal landed property. The communal property has an area of 656,000 hectares. Its greater part, that is about 55 per cent., is pastureland. Woodland constitutes 30 per cent, and the rest is arable land. The words woodland and pastureland must be given the denotation we have already explained. On the pastureland the animals of all the members of a commune are pastured. In the woods animals are pastured and wood is cut. In this connection woodcutting properh'^ so-called must be distinguished from the gathering of leaves for forage. Woodcutting is undertaken without any method and the result is real devastation. Arable land is let by farming contracts. This generally takes place in the islands of the north. Cultivatois settled on land belonging to the communes enjoy slightly better conditions than those on private land. In its capacity as proprietor the commune is satisfied with little, as a rule one seventh of the yield converted into cash. Communal property constitutes an inexhaustible source of.controversy among the members of one commune and among adjacent communes. In a government report of 1870 it was said to produce a little grass and many lawsuits. The shepherds are well armed while the3^ pasture their flocks and are almost always at war with members of their commune or with the shepherds of adjacent communes. Communal property is being more and more reduced in extent b}^ en- croachments on the part of those members of comnumes who are protected by the communal council. These are declared to be proprietors after they have been occupiers for a certain number of years. But it is not rare for a second encroachment to supersede the first on the occasion of a change in the communal council. Until 1850 the communes paid no taxes on their property because their members paid a tax as usufructories. From 1850 the State placed a land tax on the communal propert}^ and the contribution of the usufructories was thereafter paid to the communes. Until 1850 no change was introduced into communal property. In that 3'ear, after the cadaster had been established, it became Hable, as has been said, to the land tax. In the same year occurred the first scheme for the distribution of communal property to the members of communes. There have been many subsequent and similar schemes. For twent3'-six years none of them produced any effect ; but on 27 March 1876 they had an important result, namely the promulgation of the law on the distribution of communal property. The terms of this law are as follows : 1. The distribution of communal property' is optional. Every com- mune may either distribute it or retain it as communal. 2. Distribution is made on the following conditions : a) A majority of the communal council must have voted in favour of a proposed distribution. SOME AGRICULTURAL PROBLEMS IN DALMATIA 89 b) It must he accepted by an absolute majority of all the inhabi - tants registered by the census of the commune. 3. The distribution among the members of the commune will be made by the communal authorities, assisted b^' a surve^'or. 4. Before a distribution is made the land which it should not affect, that is the land which will remain the commune's property, will be surrounded b^^ a hedge. Hitherto 12,000 hectares have been distributed in fourteen communes, in accordance with this law. § 5. Redivision. We will devote a few words to the problem of redi vision. It has already been said that landed property in Dalmatia is too much scattered, many proprietors owning from fifty to eighty parcels of land. In -vdew of this state of affairs redivision would be very useful. It is however very rarely proposed and the law on subidvision promulgated in 18S3 has never been applied. The reason for these circumstances is not hard to seek. The problems of the farming contracts and of the distribution of landed property are distinct. That of division cannot however be solved finally, in view of existing agrarian relations, until after the two former. If a redivision were to be undertaken today it could be only provisional and would have to be renewed after the other two problems had been solved. Owing to such dependence on other questions redivision cannot be considered in isolation. Redivision was last proposed in 19 10 by Deputy Sununcitch, who suggested that it should be undertaken simultaneously with the solution of the problems of the farming contracts and of the di'^tribution of communal property, UNITED STATES. FARM TENANCY IN THE UNITED STATES by Prof. Benjamin H. Hibbard, University of Wisconsin. Introduction. So far as the authentic history of tenancy in the United States is concerned it ma^^ be said to begin with the year 1880 since at that time the first tenancy census was taken. The percentage of farms operated by ten- ants for the four census years, by divisions, were as follows : United States North Atlantic division South Atlantic division North Central division . South Central division. Western division . . . I9IO 1900 1890 1880 37-0 35-3 28.4 25.5 18.2 20.8 18.4 16.0 45-9 44.2 38.5 36.1 28.9 27.9 33-4 20.5 517 48.6 38.5 36.2 14.1 16.6 12. 1 14.0 It will be seen that in 1880, about one in four farms was operated by a tenant ; in 1910 almost two out of five were in the tenant group. Unques- tionably the proportion is somewhat higher by this time than it was six years ago. The number of tenant farms increased 130 per cent, during the thirty year period coveredby the statistics, while during the same time there was an increase of but 34 per cent, in the number of farms worked by owners. At these disproportionate rates of increase it will take but another three decades to result in a larger number of tenants than landowning farmers, thus making us unmistakably a nation of tenants and landlords. It is, however, by no means certain that the proportion of tenants will continue to show an uninterrupted increase. In fact the increase has alread}^ ceased, and a turn in the other direction been made, according to the last census, in tweWe FARM TENANCY 9 1 of the older States. There was also a decrease in tenancy percen- tages in several of the newer States but the significance of the change in these States is different from that in the older settled part of the country. Tenanc}- reaches its highest point in the cotton belt. For instance in Georgia two thirds of all farms are rented. The percentage is also high in the corn belt ; in Illinois over two fifths of the farms are rented, and largely in the best part of the State, It is, then, plain that the growth of tenancy in the United vStates has for at least three decades been rapid. Before the year 1880, there had undoubt- edly been a much less rapid growth, yet it had reached important propor- tions nevertheless. The question may very properly be asked why so many farms should be farmed by others than their owners. Especially is this a pertinent question in view of the fact that within a half century the federal government has disposed of immense tracts of public domain on terms so favourable as to make ownership easy and the necessity of renting land of a landlord remote. Several hundred million acres of land have within a half century either been granted free of charge to the settler, or sold at such low prices as to suggest a gift. And this plan of disposing of the land was with the conscious idea of putting land into the hands of the men who should acquire it for their own use. And yet upon much of the land given awa3^ or sold for S 1-25 per acre during the seventies or the eighties, are now to be found tenants, in many instances as man}^ tenants as owners. The causes of this remarkable development of a tenant class, if class it may be called, are complex. In the first place it may be remarked that ver\' few American farmers prefer to be tenants rather than owners. So far as the man on the farm is concerned he is either the owner or a prospective owner. The young man expects to rent land, but always with the hope and the expectation that the tenancy will lead to ownership. Farmers remain tenants because they find the price of land high, or sometimes it may mean that the price of the farm is high not so much because of high price per acre as because it requires many acres to make an efficient unit. High price per acre would rule in the case of truck farming land, in fruit land, irrigated districts, or in general farm land near a great city. High cost of the farm as a whole, due primarily to great size, would obtain in the wheat belt and still more in the grazing belt. But whichever the cause, the fact remains that it is no easy matter for a young man to gain possession of a farm worth Sio,ooo to §20,000. Somebody must make a considerable payment on a farm of this kind before the owner is willirg to take a mortgage for the balance, or a bank is willing to advance the funds. Kearly two thirds of the farms rented are rented for a share of the pro- duct. Out of each hundred farms, twenty-four are rented in whole or in part on shares, and thirteen are rented for cash. The cash rent as used in the census figures does not always means actual money, but instead signifies some other form of fixed payment, such as a specified quantity of cotton. It cannot be said that one form of rent payment is good and the other bad, 92 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL or that one is even better than the other. There are, however, advantages of each from the standpoint of both landlord and tenant. For instance cash rent is simpler ; there is no room for disagreement as to amount, or as to time of paj'ment. It is supposed that cash payment of rent signifies a more independent position of the tenant. He is free to do as he pleases in many particulars. Under the condition of cash rent the landlord as a rule exer- cises relativel}^ little control over the management of the farm. In fact inability or unwillingness to do so is a prime reason on his part for prefer- ring cash, even though somewhat less in amount than share rent. The prob- lem to the landlord of sales of produce is eliminated in the case of cash pay- ment, and all fear of an unfair division eliminated. On the contran,' there are manj^ advantages to both parties in the shar- ing of the income. The tenant runs less risk, since in case of a failure or partial failure of crops, he is permitted to pay a rental proportionate to the income instead of a cash charge much beyond it. Moreover, it requires less capital on the tenai-t's part to start farming on shares since under these circumstances he furnishes but half, or possibly some other fraction, of the live stock, feed, and seed needed. As an offset to these advantages the tenant has less freedom of choice in running the farm, though he has the advantage of the landlord's more mature judgement. Control over the farm and its management is one of the foremost reasons for preferring to let land out on shares instead of for cash. It is the general belief on the part of landlords that on an average the returns are greater in the case of share than of cash rent. This is unquestionably true when prices of produce are above normal, or during a period of rising prices such as has obtained during the past fifteen or twenty years. For twentj^ years after the first tenancy census was taken cash rent gained much more rapidly than share rent and it looked as though it was to become the prevailing S5'stem. Then came the census of 1910, with the information that cash rented farms had increased in number but half as rapidly as those rented for a share. This was so pro- nounced a change as to call for an explanation. While other factors may have entered, the outstanding one seems to be that with the rise in prices of farm produce the share going to the landlord increased rapidly, sa rapidly in fact that it was hard to pull cash rent up to the same level. As a cortse- quence landlords were anxious to change from the cash to the share system. Tenants, although not usually so anxious for the change, would acquiesce rather than run the risk on a much increased cash basis. Even the weather may have played a part, since a prolonged series of wet years made crops un- certain in many districts and caused a change in the minds of tenants in favour of share paj^ment. The most encouraging form of tenancy is where landlord and tenant share in both management and income, becoming as it were partners. FARM TENAMCY 93 § I. lyENGTH OF TENANCIES. According to the best information available a tenant stays on a given farm hardly three years. The share tenants move a little oftener than do those paying cash. In contrast to the short period of occupancy by ten- ants the farms operated b^^ owners are held by a given owner probably about sixteen years. Thus even the owners are not in the habit of staying on the same farm permanently. It must be remembered that America is a new country, and that there is still a strong tendency among farmers to move west and take advantage of the cheaper price of land. Likewise there are many small farms sold in order to purchase larger ones. As a result the farm population at best is not extremely stable. Tenants are continually on the mtDve because of a variety of circum- stances. Many times it has been said that the short lease is the curse of American tenant farming. But the short lease is the result rather than the cause of evils. American farm land has been rising rapidly in value. It has been, in consequence, for sale. As a result of these facts many a farm chang- es occupants because of a change in ownership, and the owner, so long as he holds the farm for sale, is bound to lease it for short periods of time. Another important cause of short tenures is the fact that the tenants are themselves developing into farm ow'ners. In the normal course of events a 3-oung man starts farming on a small scale, and therefore wants a small farm. A few years later he is better satisfied with a somewhat larger farm, and hence moves if he finds an opportunity, as he usually does. But fully as important as the desire to rent a bigger farm is the prospect of owning a farm for himself. The rate at which tenants become owners is growing somewhat slower. Nevertheless the great majority of those who stay in the farming business a lifetime manage by some means to become landowners. Of all farmers below the age of twenty-five, over three fourths are tenants, whereas of those over sixty-five years of age about six sevenths are owners. It is thus plain that the short periods of occupancy of farms by tenants is in no small measure due to the constant rise of tenant^ to ownership on their own account. § 2. Speculation and tenancy. Very closely related to length of tenure and to the amount of tenancy is speculation in land. From the very beginning of the public land policies of the country speculation on the part of individuals has played a major role. The cheap government price has alwa\'s been tempting to investors, and rare indeed is the case of land which has not been held many years primarih^ for the rise in value. This speculative period has lasted well beyond the early years when land was cheap, and mainly unused. It pre- 94 UNITED STAGES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL vails to a great extent throughout the country today. The speculator wants to get what he can out of the land while he holds it and thus puts it on the market for rent. He is even willing to take a very moderate ren- tal rather than not let it at all, and above all he will not tie his own hands with a long lease. In parts of the grain belt where speculation has reached its greatest development half of the farms are rented. The landlords when asked whether or not the investment is a paying one are likelj^ to reply that the rise in land values makes it pay, though rent alone would not. So long as land continues to rise in value, so long will it be the object of specula- tion, and so long as non-farmers are tempted to buy it for speculation, so long again will it be offered for rent. The relationship between specula- tion and rent is a close one. , I^est the reasoning concerning this point seem to be unduly deductive it may be said that in the older parts of the United States, where the rise in values has become much less rapid than formerly, and especially much less rapid than in the Middle West , the percentage of tenanc}^ is in the first place lower than a few years ago, and in the second place decidedly lower than in the latter section. Moreover, in Europe where farm land is much more stable in value than in America^ tenures are likewise more stable. So long as there are such splendid opportunities for profitable investments to be made in American farm lands, there is sure to be a conti- nuation or even an increase in the proportion of farms owned by one class and operated by another. § 3. Tenancy and types of agriculture. The evidence is abundant to show that tenancy follows as the natur- al outcome of conditions, and one of the most important of the conditions is the character of the agriculture in practice. The tenant is transient. Consequently he is bound to adapt himself to an environment which ad- mits of relatively easy shifts. He must get into the routine quickly on arrival at his new home, and must be able to take his possessions along with him from the farm he is leaving. This means that he owns relatively little live stock, that he plants few perennials or biennials, that he invests little money in fertilizers or sub-soil ploughs. The tenants deal with animals and crops that can be made to yield their increase within twelve months. In the truck districts they grow tomatoes, but not asparagus ; potatoes, but not rhubarb. What the tenant wants is a chance to sow, harv^est and sell, all within a year. It is therefore not surprising that tenancy is most pre- valent in the greatest cotton, corn, and wheat districts. In the cotton belt all things seem to conspire to divorce the ownership from the tillage of the soil. The crop is given within the year ; it requires but little capital on the part of the tenant, and but little improvement in the way of buildings and fences on the part of the land level. In the corn belt the broad acres capable of cultivation on a wholesale plan, with the prospect of much pro- FARM TENANCY 95 duce for the market within a few months, appeal strongly to the man who can command relatively more labour than capital. The northern tenant is a grain producer and grain seller. He produces more grain of every kind than is produced by the landowning farmer. This means that the tenant raises less of the crops vised for feeding young stock, such as hay and pasture crops. The grain which he raises has two main mar- kets. One market is the city ; the other is the neighbouring farmer who feeds stock, feeds more grain than he can raise. The tenant does not go extensively into such business as dairying and for very obvious and important reasons. He must have, in order to do dair3-ing successfully, well equipped barns, milk house, fences and the like. The landlord does not care to furnish facilities of this kind, especially the landlord who holds the farm mainly for speculation. Or again the land- lord who lives at a distance from the farm hesistates to put up man}^ improve- ments of this kind because of the rapid deterioration in careless hands, and many tenants are careless with property which is not their own. Another reason why tenants do not care especially to go into a business like dairying is because it makes it much harder to move and adjust themselves to farms, barns, and surroundings, such as they are likely to find in another neigh- bourhood. By moving they may not only be obliged to put up with equip- ment less adequate, but they may, by going ten miles, get away from market- ing opportunities, such as milk routes, creameries, or cheese factories. The tenant is not a cattle feeder because of lack of capital required in hand- ling the business, and lack of equipment for handling the cattle and the feed. The tenant seldom goes into specialized farming such as fruit growing. Fruit growing is a continuous process extending over some years. The ten- ant has no security of tenure such as to warrant investment in trees, shrubs and labour such as fruit growing requires. Neither does he have charac- ter, habits and skill so developed as to make it desirable to lease him a fruit farm which has already been put into shape. The chances are that he will be much more interested in the crop in sight than in subsequent harvests. Only two to four per cent, of the citrus fruits are grown by ten- ants and an unimportant part of the commercially grown apples are so pro- duced. vSpecialized farming, such as tobacco or vegetable growing, lends itself very well to tenant conditions, since these crops require little equip- ment, and but few months. vSumming up the question of the relation of type of agriculture to tenancy, it appears that the tenant is an exploiter of the soil. He does a hand-to-mouth business, and not much may be expected of the farmer whose interests in the farm begin and end within a space of two or three years. Relative Profits Made by Tenants and Landoietning Farmers. It is usually taken for granted that tenants are poor. As shown above they have not accumulated a great deal of property from their own opera- tions. Not a great many young farmers inherit a fortune, and even should 96 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL they inherit a considerable amount of property it is hkely to fall into their hands in middle Ufe , not when thej^ are making a beginning as farmers. The tenant is, without doubt, in most cases a poor man. How^ever,. he is not doomed to remain a poor man always. Somewhat surprising was the result of a government sur\'ey made a few years ago into the condition of over seven hundred representative farmers in several northern States. It appears from this sur^'e3"[that tenants make a larger labour income than do landown- ing farmers. This is another way of saying that under present conditions and circumstances farming as a business does not return a large percentage on the investment. In other v/ords, land rentals have been capitalized at a low rate of interest and in consequence land values are high. Rentals do not rise as readil}- as the selling value of land and, therefore, other things being equal, it is cheaper to rent land than to bu}^ it. Of course, other things are by no means equal, and it would be hazardous to say that it is better to rent than to buy, but it is safe to say that one must pay for the advantages of owning land. The tenants have more to show for a year's work, so far as immediate income is concerned, than have farmers who own the bnd they work. This is true if five per cent, interest be charged on the investment in land . Turning the problem around, it may be shown that, since the landowner earns fully as much as a labourer as does the tenant, he has but three to three and a half per cent, interest on his investment. This suggests strongly that the prices of land are too high, and that a farmer will do better to rent than to buy. However, land is stiU rising in value, especially in the parts of the country where tenancy' is prevalent, and the owner has the advantage of the increase in value while the tenant does not. Add to this the great ad- vantage in ha\ang control over the operations of a farm for a considerable period of years, the satisfaction of staying in one place and building up a business, and, all told, it suggests caution in advising a man who is able to buy to refrain from doing so. The labour income of the tenant is indeed larger than that of the landowning farmer, but the accumulated wealth at the end of a few years is larger in the case of the landowner. § 4. Relation of tenancy to permanent agriculture. The (H^estion maj' well be asked whether tenancy is or is not compatible with the maintenance of soil fertility. In England it has been found pos- sible to keep the soil up to its best over several generations of a landlord- tenant system. But in England the landlords are neither retired farmers, hoping to leave as large an estate in immediate value as possible, nor yet are they speculators who hope to make a sale at an advanced price. The interest of the landlord in the land is a permanent one, and as a corollary to this the interest of the tenant in the land is hardly less permanent. The tenant moves ver\' infrequently and has no hope, usually no desire, to buy land. As the tenant does desire to have the land continue to yield well. FARM TENANCY 97 he is willing to make investments to that end, but he does not want to lose the investment in the event of leaving the farm. In America we have hardh^ reached the point of taking such matters into consideration. First, the land- lord usually owns the farm but a decade or two, and the soil will not be greatly depleted in so short a time. Secondly, the tenant who is to stay but a quarter of a decade can hardly take any profound interest in building up the soil. Thus the arrangement which most often obtains impels neither landlord nor tenant to take a great deal of interest in permanent agriculture. The landlord expects to sell the land ; the tenant expects to leave it. Very little is invested in fertilizers throughout the grain belt ; the tenant very rarely puts any sort of improvement upon the land. Hence, there is but Httle over which to debate concerning rights when the farm changes hands. It cannot be held that the fertility is being maintained on the great ma- jority of rented farms. In the very best parts of the country the contrary is the case. True, the census reports show that tenants raise about as much grain per acre as is raised by the owners. This is accounted for in part by the fact that the tenant farms are not a separate group always rented, as distinguished from another group always operated by owner?. There is a good deal of interchange. But after all, the fact that the tenants raise about as much produce per acre as the owners proves too much. The tenant sells a large part of his produce in the bulky form of field crops, and tliis in itself must eventually result in soil depletion, The tenant has decidedly less interest in soil maintenance than has the landlord, and the landlord's in- terest under present conditions is little enough. When stable values elimi- nate the speculator, and when few farmers can retire on the strength of unearn- ed increment gains, then we shall have a class of landlords who take a more fundamental interest in the soil and likewise a class of tenants who can afford to co-operate in the up-building of better farming. The laws at present do not protect the tenant in his right to improve- ments. On the other hand it is a rare thing for the tenant to wish to make improvements. He may complain because improvements are inadequate, he ma}^ urge the landlord to improve; more likely he will move to another farm if conditions are found to be to bad. But that he should put improve- ments of anj' sort on the farm will seldom occur to an American tenant. Should laws be made protecting the tenant in this right, it is more than Ukely that gradually tenants would begin a new regime of land improvement, but it would never progress far while the tenure is, on an average, so short. § 5. Tenancy and marketing problems. One of the worst of the tenant evils is the helpless condition in which the tenant is placed with respect to marketing. It is folly to ])roceed with pro- cesses leading always to greater production without taking the marketing possibilities into account. The tenant is a poor bargainer in the market be- 98 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL cause so often he is forced to sell almost immediately. In the South the cot- ton tenant is nearly always in debt for the supplies of the 3'ear, and his obli- gations are due i October, or i November. This means that he must sell his cotton almost at the earliest possible moment after it is harvested. In farmers' organizations the tenants are very poorly represented. An inves- tigation made a 3'ear ago showed that in sections of the grain belt, where tenants are almost as numerous as owners and substantially always grain sellers, the membership in co-operative companies was but one fourth tenants. This means that only half as high a proportion of tenants as owners belonged to the marketing organizations. In other words while ten- ants seU more grain than owners, there are three owners to one tenant in the selling company. Tenants as a class are seldom found in organizations. They do not join since they are so likely to move, or on account of lack of mone}', or again on account of indifference. Tenants are poor community members. It is not their fault alto- gether but rather the fault of the system. They cannot be good community members in very solid ways since that implies investment, and for a tenant to invest in schools, roads or churches means an investment for which he gets no title. When a farm owner sells out, he sells his right to community investments along with the farm. When a tenant moves he takes his per- sonal property along with him, and if he has any interest in community property he leaves it behind. As a result he is usually careful that little is created to be so left. § 6. The outlook. What then is the outlook ? Is America doomed to become a nation of landlords and tenants ? True, the proportion of tenants is on the increase, but not in quite all sections. Neither is there an increase in tenancy in all kinds of farming. Another fact that is fairly encouraging is that along with the increase in tenancy there is little tendency toward centralization in land ownership. In about 60 per Cent, of the instances of tenanc}^ the owner of the farm owns but the one. And moreover the tenant farms differ little in size from owned farms. Thus landlords own but little more land than is owned by an equal number of landowning farmers. Of course there are many important and unfortunate exceptions to this. Such exceptions are found oftener than an^'where else in the cotton belt, where the owner- ship of several farms by one man is not uncommon. Tenancy has often been called a step in the agricultural ladder. The figure of speech is a ver\' good one, since the majorit}' of tenants rise to owrership. However the step is a more difficult one to take now than it was a decade or a quarter century ago. Should it continue to become more difficult for another generation, we must eventually face the fact of a tenant FARM TEXAXCY 99 class, a class which can hardl^^ be said to exist outside of the coloured popu- lation of the South. The tide will turn in favour of ownership if ever we reach the stage where the speculative value of land disappears ; where few farmers are able to retire on the basis of wealth accruing through unearned increment ; and where, therefore, land is worth a sum based on its productivity. This is on the assumption that a system of agricultural credit favourable to the farmers will in the meantime be worked out. One of the main rea- sons why it seems safe to suggest that these conditions will result in owner- ship rather than tenancy is because it is not likely that an}' S3'stem will soon be devised whereby the fertility of the soil will be as well conserved under a tenant system as under a system of ownership. MISCElvIvANKOUS INFOR]\IATION REI.ATING TO AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAI,. AUSTRALIA. I, AND SETTIvHMENT IN 19 15- 191 6 New South Wales. — The annual report of the Lands Department for the year ending 30 June 1916 shows that in that 3^ear 2,279,417 acres of land became available for settlement in New South Wales. Areas aggregating 1,345,218 acres were withdrawn from long leases and 535,478 acres were resumed. Four estates were acquired under the Closer Set- tlement Acts. In all thirty-four estates, providing 1660 farms, were ac- quired. Forty-six of these farms, comprising 41,637 acres, were vacant on 30 June 1916. The following figures show the progress of settlement on the various estates acquired under the Closer Settlement Acts : — Number of farms allotted, 1609 ; area allotted, 748,573 acres ; persons resident, 7,410 ; area prepared for cultivation, 357,591 acres ; value of improvements, £1,149,802; value of plant and machinery, £326,844 ; number of horses, 17,584 ; sheep, 191,924 ; cattle 12,610. The report of the Western Land Board states that, owing to the con- tinuance of drought and the absence of so many men at the war, there was little demand for land in the western division. Seven new leases were issued and concerned an aggregate area of 29,936 acres. The receipts for the year amounted to £90,073 and the expenditure to £10,518. Victoria. — As regards Victoria the report of the Lands Department for the year ending 30 June 1916 states that the absence on mihtary service of a large proportion of the young men of the State was a grave deterrent to new settlement. The following figures show its progress in the year : — 568 holdings aggregating 101,556 acres, exclusive of Mallee land, new- ly selected ; 238 holdings of Mallee land, aggregating 140,325 acres, newly selected; 146 holdings aggregating 46,522 acres selected out of grazing area leaseholds ; 179 holdings aggregating 3,175 acres converted to selec- tion tenure. There was an appreciable decline in the demand for Mallee land. It was hoped in the esaXy part of the year that the exceptionally large wheat harvest would result in considerable payments of the arrears of rent due to the department, but against this the war conditions operated. These arrears on 30 June.1915 were on crown lands, £49,233 i8s. 5^. and on Mallee lands £127,184 is. 5^,; and on 30 June 1916 they were £45,141 on crown lands and £140,060 on Mallee lands. Not less NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL lOI than one third of the amount advanced for the purchase of seed and fodder should have been a charge on the returns of 1915-1916, but the ministry decided to make no deduction from the advance of 2s. 6d. a bushel, and to defer the collection of instalments until a further amount, or dividend, should have been paid. Tliis concession seriously reduced the amount received as repa3'ment of advances. Up to the end of the financial year a sum of £95,535 was repaid out of the total sum of money lent in the pre- vious 3'ear, £516,000. Of the balance one third is payable from the 1916 harvest and one third ma}' be carried on to the next year. For the year 1916 the number of crop liens registered was 3,032. BRITISH INDIA. THE COLONIZATION OF CANAL LANDS IN THE PUNJAB. — Van Burren Henry L- in The Tropical Agrmdturist Vol. XLVII., No. 6, Peradenij'a (Ceylon), December 1916. The south western Punjab is part of a vast desert which may be said to extend from the Sahara to Manchuria. It supported only a sparse and nomadic population until 1849, when the British annexed this part of the Punjab, and colonization of its desert wastes was not seriously thought of until 1885 when a policy of canal irrigation was initiated. Five great perennial canals, which together irrigate a wheat area rather more than twice the size of Ceylon, were then taken in hand. One of them, completed in 1892, commands three and a third million acres, three fourths of such area being State property, and irrigates over two and a half mil- lion acres a year. The capital expended on it was 300 lacs of rupees (i) which now bring in interest at the average rate of about 28 per cent. An- other canal which was finished about 1911 irrigates some three quarters of a milHon acres and pays interest on the capital invested in it at the rate of more than 10 per cent. Before 1892 the population of the Ivyallpur district could not have been more than 2,000. In 1912 it had increased to over 850,000. To settle so large an agricultural population was no easy matter. The problem needed wise statesmanship, a very intimate knowledge of the peas- ant farmer and his ideas, enthusiasm and a kindly sympathy. That these are of more importance than the principles on which projects and schemes were based should be emphasized. Thus Sir James Douie writes : — " The colonies have been admirable training ground for the ablest of the yoiinger Punjab officers. It was necessary to give them a pretty free hand, the work was novel and important, and involved great responsibilities. While he was controlled from outside, the colony officer inside his colony had to be a benevolent autocrat. Autocracy is tolerable when the autocrat is con- tent to be also the servant of liis people, and in this respect the Punjab offi- cers did not show themselves lacking ". (i) I lac — • i,oo,oof rupees; i rupee = is \d. 102 NOTICES REIvATlXG TO AGRlCULTUEAIv ECONOMY IX GENERAL It must not be thought that no mistakes were made, for the problems were novel and at times very difficult. Nor must it be thought that there were no setbacks. Plague invaded the province in 1897 and broke out virulently in the canal districts in 1904 and 1907. Outbreaks of cholera were also frequent. In 1905 crops were injured by frost and almost the whole crop of cotton was destroyed by the boll-worm. The settlement scheme has now passed the experimental stage and stands out as one of the most notable achievements of British administra- tion in India. Sir James I/yaU's name will always be associated with this work. He gave his conception of a scheme of colonization thus : — " An attempt should be made to establish estates owned by bodies of peasant propietors. [The Punjab is chiefly a country of small holdings]. In the eastern part of the Punjab and in the sub-Himalayan tracts there are found not infre- quently villages peopled by agrictdturists of the best type, who have in- creased in numbers until the lands which they own are insufficient for their support ; often the owners of such estates have been accustomed to culti- vate as tenants in neighbouring villages. But, owing to the owners of those villages now requiring the lands for themselves, (they) are gradually being ejected. It would improve the general condition... if some of the proprietors would emigrate to other countries... A number of men of this class might be induced to settle in the Gujranwala Bar by being allowed to migrate in bodies... formed by themselves, and by the promise on cer- tain conditions of grants of land ... The experiment might be tried in the following way.... Go to places in the thickl}' populated districts, where groups of adjacent villages are owned by men of the same clan, and.... search among them for men of some amount of enterprise, capital and influence, and ask such men..... to lead down bodies of men of their own clan to the government lands irrigated by the canal. Well selected blocks would be made over to the bodies so migrating. The leader of the colony would be given an interest in its success not only by receiving a share in the pro- prietorship but also by his being made headman of the new estate ". Sir James Lyall thought it " essential to preserve the tradition of the Punjab as a country of peasant farmers ". He however made three kinds of grants. " Yeoman grants " were to attract a class above the ordinary peasantrj^ — the middle class. " Capitalist " holdings were granted so as to supply " natural leaders for the new society ". It is interesting to note that yeoman and capitalist grants have been given up. Grants of land to native officials for meritorious service are condemned as a result of ex- perience. Grants are occasionally made, however, to members of the her- editary landed gentry. The peasant farmers' settlements were most suc- cessful, and from settlers on them leaders and captains of industry are gradually arising. The system of allocating land now approved is to give each peasant a rectangle of twenty-five acres. On fulfilling the conditions of the lease he can, after five years, acquire a permanent right of occupancy, which can be converted into ownership if he pay the market value of the land, as de- NOTICES REI.ATIXG TO AGRICULTRAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL IO3 duced from auction sales, less a fixed percentage. The purchase money may be paid in instalments which may extend over thirty years. Until it is paid the settler remains a tenant, and pays R. i an acre, in addition to water rates, land revenue and cesses. The pioneering attempts to colonize the land allowed the settler, after five years and on fulfilling the terms of the lease, to acquire ownership bj^ pa3'ing onl}' Rs. 3 an acre. Subsequent modifications were due to the eager competition for the land after pioneering difficulties had been over- come. Before the land was let out on leases contour maps of the irrigable lands were made and the areas served b}- separate water-courses defined. Village areas were made to coincide with water-course areas, and each vil- lage was subdivided into squares or rectangles which formed the units for allotment. It was found necessary later also to survey the soil before al- lotment ; for there must be discrimination between good and mediocre land and land too poor for cultivation, if it be desired that water-courses should not be carried uselessly into land not worth irrigating, and many difficulties raised. The selection of peasant settlers, their location on the land and care for their future welfare are by no means the least part of the scheme, but may on the contrary be said to sum it up. It is to work of the kind which has been emphasized that the success of this colonization is largely due. BRITISH WEST INDIES. THE PROGRESS OF LAND SETTLE:VIENT IN GRENADA. The Report of the Agricultural Department for 1915-1916 shows con- siderable activity in Grenada in the matter of land settlement. The gov- ernment acquired the estate known as the St. Cyr Mountain I^ands, sit- uated about ten miles from St. Georges, for £2,184, which sum with the cost of a survey and of road construction and other expenses brought the total cost up to £3,597-105. The roads for the purpose of giving access from every lot to the by-ways of the district cost £235 and their total length was three and a half miles. Their construction, and that of a connection, one and a half miles long, between the Beauregard and Adelphi by-ways, were carried out by the Agricultural Department. Thirty-six lots bear cacao or mixed cacao and nutmeg trees on a quarter of an acre or more land, on their entire area in only a few cases. Other eighty- four lots are bus'h or forest land. The average area of a lot is two acres. The lots on which there is cacao were sold at from about £14 to £35 an acre, according to the number and condition of the trees ; the unculti- vated lots at £io-ios and £12 an acre. Purchasers of the more costly lots, which contained cacao, had to pay a deposit of at least is 3^ and the balance of the total price in five annual instalments. The uncultiva- 104 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL ted land was sold on the usual land settlement terms. One fourth or one twelfth of the price was deposited : and the balance is to be paid when a fourth has been deposited, in nine annual instalments of which the first falls due three years after the allotment ; and when onh- a twelfth has been deposited, in eleven annual instalments beginning a year after alio - ment. Interest is charged on all unpaid instalments at the rate of 5 per cent. A special committee of the district board of St. Andrew's parish, in which the settlement is situated, co-operated with the Agricultural Depart- ment in selecting desirable settlers. Two hundred and ninety-one appli- cations were considered. The superintendent's report on the valuation of the lots for sale was submitted in March 1915. The first applications were dealt with in April, and by the end of the year under review practically all the lots had been allotted and occupied. They are. being worked, except a few of those occu- pied lately, and on some ver>" good progress has been made. These results are on the whole very satisfactory, and are proof of the activity of the Agri- cultural Department even in its present understaffed condition. The estate is well watered by four tributaries of the Fond Perdu River ; and the climate is damp, the annual rainfall being estimated at 100 inches. The soil is mostly a fairly deep loam, dark brown in colour, and the subsoil red clay, interspersed with boulders about two feet below the surface which crop out here and there. The subsoil is rather close in texture, but the surface soil is fairly friable and therefore can be improved by tillage and drainage. It is well suited to the cultivation of ground crops. The cacao can be considerabh^ improved, particularly b}^ draining the land and ad- ding organic matter to enhance its permanent fertilit3^ The estate is fertile except in the south-east corner. It has two warm mineral springs, one at the west end and one in the river. FRANCE. AGRICULTURAL WAGES DURING THE WAR. — Communication mad e by M. Paul Vincey to the Academic d' Agriculture de France at the meeting of 21 March 1917. M. Paul Vincey resumes as follows the facts as to the increase in agri- cultural wages which has occurred during the present war in the district of Paris, more particularly in the three departments of Seine, Seine- et-Oise and Seine-et-Marne. As is the case everywhere in France mobilization has reduced the available supply of labour by the enormous amount of two thirds, or even perhaps three fourths. For reasons easy to understand the production of the labourers who have remained on the soil or have come to it — old men, women, children, refugees from the north, soldiers on leave — has also diminished markedly, apparently by one third as compared with the normal production before the war. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 105 The following table shows for the three years 1914 (before the war) 1915 and 1916 and the district under consideration the average wages of per- sons lodged and fed and otherwise, paid by the day, the month and the piece, and employed on the special works of dressing and uprooting beetroot and of the hay and corn-harvests. These wages are paid in the three departments within the district considered. It should be remembered that in Seine wages are generally higher and in Seine-et-Marne lower than in Seine-et-Oise, where they reach an intermediary level. Agriadiural Wages in the District of Paris. Class of Labourer Employees neither lodged nor fed Francs (i) 1915 1916 Employees lodged aud fed 1914 1915 1916 Journeymen Workmen Mechanics Threshers Smiths, harness- makers, wheel-wrights Harvesters . Mowers . . Ha%Tnakers . Farm clerks Ploughmen . Cattle herds Shepherds . Cowmen . . Farm servants Men . . Women Dressing beetroot Uprooting beetroot ....'. Mowing Harvest {reaping and binding) Daily II 10 6 Daily Wages, 6 2 550 2 8.50 6.50 7-50 Wages for Special Work. 450 5.50 6 2 3 4-50 5 5-50 2 2.50 6.50 7-50 8.50 5 5-50 6.50 550 6.50 7-50 13 15 12 14 7 8 Monthly Wages. 270 300 160 190 170 180 75 90 160 170 75 85 150 160 75 80 155 160 75 80 140 150 65 75 100 no 50 55 1 230 150 140 140 145 130 90 Wages for 3-50 3 70 80 90 60 70 80 30 40 50 60 85 100 210 100 90 85 85 80 60 Piece-Work per Hectare (2) (i) I franc = 9 3/5 d. at par (2) i hectare = 2.47 acres. I06 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL These results, which were obtained by a correspondence with persons in the industry, should be regarded only as giving the averages obtaining in the Paris district. In manj^ cases the wages in use are above, or below those in the table. For a working day the wages given as those of the employees who are fed are generally less by from 2.50 to 3 francs than those of similar labourers finding their Own food. It is none the less true that the cost of food rose progressively from 2.50 francs to 3.50 francs and more for one working day between 1914 and 1916. A comparison between daily and monthly wages in 1916 and 1914 shows a general increase of about 33 per cent. If the diminution already cited in average production be taken into account, it appears that the real wages of agricultural labour have increas- ed by about two thirds during the present war. This is also the rate at which the wages of piece-work, mowing and harvesting, and in many cases those of dressing and uprooting beetroot, have increased. In the Paris district the wages of military labourers — that is of men on leave or belonging to estabhshments — are as follows : Balance (every rank) 0.25 francs Indemnity for clothes 0.25 » » labour 1.65 2.15 francs, that is 5.15 francs with food which can be valued, on an average, at 3 francs a day. This rise in the price of labour is certainly the chief factor which has raised the price of the various agricultural products, as the scarcit}^ of labour is chiefl}'- responsible for the progressive diminution of agricultural production. GREAT BRITAIN AND IRKLAND. WOIVCEN WORKERS ON THE FARM. — Agricultural Gazette, London, Vol. LXXXIV, No. 2243, 25 December 1916. The suitability of women to perform many of the branches of farm and horticultural work was recognized at an early date of the war, and in order to promote their employment special steps were taken by the Board of Trade, acting in conjunction with the Board of Agriculture. The pro- gress made in the substitution of women for men in agriculture has been slow, and is in no way commensurate with that achieved in industrial NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL IO7 and commercial occupations. The difficulties attendant on the work have been most serious. Prejudice on the part of the farmers, reluctance on the part of the women, insufficiency of housing accommodation, lowness of wages, have all proved serious obstacles. To try to overcome these difficulties, a campaign of propaganda work was instituted in the spring of 1915 by .the Board of Agriculture and the Board of Trade. As a result of the combined action of the boards, local voluntary committees, known generally as Women's County War Agri- cultural Committees, have been formed. At the present time there are sixty-three such committees, whose function is : i) To carry on propaganda work to promote the employment of women in agriculture. 2) To register women, and arrange for placing them in work and for their training where necessary. 3) To increase the production of home-grown food in ever3^ village. The organization which it has been sought to establish has been in the nature of a county committee working through local committees or village registrars — the usual procedure being to divide the county into districts, each having a representative. The representatives form the county committee, in charge of the general organization, and each of them is responsible for the work carried on in liis or her own localitj^ by means of a district committee or a registrar, or both, appointed in each village. There are now 1,060 district representatives and 4,000 village registrars. In some cases the Women's County Committees have a separ- ate existence, although they work in co-operation with the men's County War Agricultural Conmiittees, called into being by Lord Selborne in August 1915. In others they are sub-committees of the War Agricultural Committees. A certificate has been issued to workers at the discretion of the committees, at the time of registration or only after proved service, or in some cases not at all. After the)' have completed thiity da^-s' service on the land, registered women are entitled to wear a government armlet of green baize which bears the royal crown in scarlet. 72,021 certificates and 62,000 armlets have been issued. It has been very difficult to obtain statistics from the committees and such as the}- have supplied are not reliable. The approximate returns indicate that nearly 140,000 women have been registered, including all who have volunteered both for whole and for part time service. In cer- tain counties — as Northumberland, Wilts, Devon, Kent and parts of lyin- colnshire — and also in Wales, women have always been on the land in large numbers, and many of these do not care to register as they think that by so doing they may make themselves liable to some form of com- pulsory' service. In one of the divisions of Lincolnshire, for instance, 599 women have been returned as registered and 2,041 as working ; and in many villages the registrars can give no accurate idea of the number working as the farmers so frequently make their own independent arrangements. It appears that the comparatively small demand by I08 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL farmers for the service of women up to the last few months has been due in the main to the following reasons : (i) The number of farm labourers exempted. (2) The fact that the shortage of labour has been largely met by : a) Release of soldiers. b) Release of school children. c) Increased use of machinery d) A lower standard of cultivation. (3) The unwillingness on the part of large numbers of farmers to employ women. (4) The diflficulty of providing accommodation for imported women. The housing problem in rural districts, alread}' existent before the war, has been much intensified by the fact that the wives and families of men who joined the colours have been permitted to remain in their cot- tages. The result of this has been that the farmer has often been unable to replace the men either by other men or by women. The work undertaken bj^ the woman worker on the land is of a diverse character, and includes some occupations which do not in any wa3', as a rule, fall witliin the women's province. The following is a list of occupations in which women have been and are now engaged in various parts of the country : — I. General farm work — (a) cleaning land ; {b) stone picking; (c) weed- ing ; (d) thistle cutting ; (e) manure spreading ; (/) singling and hoeing turnips ; (g) potato setting and lifting ; and (/?) vegetable planting and transplanting. 2. Milking. 3. Stock tending and rearing. 4. Butter mak- ing. 5. Cheese making. 6. Poultry rearing. 7. Haymaking. 8. Har- vesting, g. Sheep shearing. 10. Thatching. 11. Stacking. 12. Plough- ing. 13. I.oading and unloading. 14. Threshing. 15. Fruit picking 16. Hop picking. 17. Reed stripping. 18. Bark puling. 19. Timber felling. 20. Gardening — (a) jobbing ; (b) market gardening ; (c) domestic gardening ; {d) cultivating allotments and waste land ; and {e) co- operative gardening. The experience gained during the war goes to prove that some women can do an>i;hing and everything on the land, and do it well, but that the average woman is useful chiefly for occupations i to 7 and for 15, 16 and 20. In numbers 2 and 3 they have shown themselves very successful. ITALY. 1. THE INSTITUTION OF A NATIONAL, I^ABOUR EXCHANGE. — L'Umanitaria, Mi- lan, No. I, 31 January 191 7. In order to provide for the placing of the labour belonging especially to agricultural and public works, the demand for which occurs now in one and NOTICES RELATING TO AGRlCUI,TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAl, lOQ now in another district, tlie Socield Umaniiaria of J\Iilan has instituted h^- bour exchanges for peasants which complete the organization of the urban labour exchanges, and also — in co-operation with the office of Emigration — has set up a National lyabour Exchange called the Ufficio Ncizionale di CoUocaDiento. The essential task of the latter is the placing of groups of labourers, that of isolated labourers being left to the office at IMilan even if the demand comes from elsewhere. The exchange places labour in Italy exclusively : outside Ital}^ this func- tion, in view of the necessity of estimating local conditions, belongs to the Office of Emigration. The exchange collects offers of labour by the medium of the sections of the Socield Umaniiaria, the local labour exchanges, the sec- retariats of emigration, the offices and chambers of labour, the trade organi- zations, and — where such associations and institutions are lacking — by means of correspondence. By the medium of such bodies or otherwise it should methodically collect the available labour supply. It provokes demands for lal;our, causing them to be directed to itself as much as possible and therefore maintaining constant relations with the ambulant chairs of agriculture, agricultural associations and committees, and — for the period of the war — with the provincial conmiissions of agriculture. In placing labour it takes into account the condition of laboiirers in the districts w^hence there is emigration, as well as unemployment in the various provin- ces, and seeks to form squadrons of labourers whose techniqvie and territorial origin give them homogeneity. It aims at the regvilation of conditions of labour by written contracts. In the case of a strike or a lock-out the placing of labour is interrupted. The exchange inspects places of employ- ment when necessary, either before labour is allocated or while work is in course. It proposes further to contribute, as suitably as possiljle and in har- mony with the work developed b}' the Socield Umanitaria, to raising the moral and intellectual standard of labourers in employment, and to spreading a knowledge of laws affecting labour, thrift, etc. There is at the exchange a commission of consultation and vigilance constituted by a representative of the general confederation of labour, a representative of the federation of labourers on the soil, a representative of the building federation and a representative of the secretariats of emigra- tion. This commission meets at lea.st once in every three months, when it takes note of the work which has been done, makes suggestions for the bet- ter working of the exchange, and sees that labour is placed in the best con- ditions. 2. A GENERAI^ COMMISSARIAT FOR FOOD CONSUMPTION. — Gazzctta Uficiale del Regno d'ltalia, Rome, No. 21, 26 Janiiarj^ I'ji/- To guarantee to the policy with regard to consumption the largest, the most prompt and the most effective development, in relation to the neces- I ro NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAI, sities arising out of present circumstances, a lieutenant's decree of i6 Jan- uary 1917 (no. 76) has provided that the powers of the government to regulate the consumption of food shall be exercised for the duration of the war by a committee composed of the Ministers of Agriculture, of the Interior, of Marine and Railwaj' Transport and of War, and a minister without a portfolio. As the organ of this committee of ministers, and dependent on it, a general commissariat for food consumption has been instituted and has the following duties : a) to requisition for the needs of public administrations and the civil population merchandise and if necessary producing establishments, fixing prices and the amount of compensation to be paid for the requisition ; b) to fix the maximum prices at which foods may be sold to the public and see that they are applied ; c) to supply imported and requisitioned mer- chandise to be sold to the public by the mediimi of local public admini- strations ; d) to authorize the eventual constitution of autonomous bodies of consumers (i) ; e) to regulate the sale and consumption of merchanchse of which there is a manifest shortage. The general commissariat takes the action necessary to the fulfil- ment of these ends and watches over the execution of all measures tending to regulate the consumption of food. It can issue ordinances for the exe- cution of provisions regarding consumption, and can decide on an}^ measure thus rendered necessary, according to the resolutions of the majority of the aforesaid committee of ministers to which it is directly responsible. Prefects and all local authorities must execute the ordinances and pro\nsions thus issued. Finally the commissariat can act towards the two houses of parlia- ment as a government commissary, in conformity with the statutes of the kingdom. 3. THE PROTECTION GIVEN BY THE PROVINCE OF FI^ORENCE TO THE ORPHANS OF PEASANTS KII,I,ED DURING THE WAR. — L'Agricoltura Toscana, Florence, No. 4, 28 Febraury 1917. Readers of this Review know that last December there was formed in Rome the Opera nazionale per gli orfani dei contadini morti in guerra, which (i) The autonomous bodies of consumers are constituted and financed by the local admin- istrations, the co-operative societies, the institutions of credit and individuals, and are destin- ed to exercise a healthy and moderating influence and even to compel private dealers to lower prices. The commissariat of which we have spoken facilitates their task in every way for it hopes to profit by the effect of their action. There are already such bodies in the pro\'iuces of Genoa, Rome, Piacenza, Portomaurizio, Siena, Mantua, Aquila, lyucca, Cosenza, Turin, Ascoli-Piceno, etc., and many others are in course of formation. In order to hasten their legal recognition the government has issued special rules and instructions. By force of the lieute- nant's decree of 11 April 1917, no. 85, the acts of their constitution are exempt from the stamp and registration duties ; and all other acts which thej' may pass after their constitution are subject to the ordinary stamp duties and are registered on payment of the fixed duty of 2.70 liias (i lira = 9 ^/g d at par). NOTICES RlCr,AT[NG TO AGRICUI.TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL III aims at promoting in Italy a complete and vast organization for helping the orphans of peasants killed in the war and giving them an agricultural training. The basis of this organization is the foundation — already accom- plished — in the respective Italian provinces of special protecting agencies (i) which propose in general to assist the orphans in two ways : to increase a widow's pension when that paid by the State is insufficient, as when the number of children is excessive ; and to see that the orphans have suitable instruction in agriculture and the necessary education, receiving them, when they cannot be maintained in their families or by their mothers, in special institutions — agricultural colonies — in which an agricultural training is given so essentially practical that they return to the soil capable of improving it and increasing its production (2). Recently, by a prefectoral decree of 27 January 1917, there was con- stituted the Patronato provincialc per gli orfani dei contadini morti in guerra which has its headquarters at Florence. It proposes to assist the orphans of peasants who have died on the field or in consequence of the state of war ; and small labourer proprietors and leaseholders, as well as labourers habituall}^ employed on fieldwork, are assimilated to peasants. The assistance takes the form of a) guardianship of rights and interests ; h) responsibility for the upbringing, education and instruction adapted to the childrens' condition and the kind of agriculture they will practise. Mor- al assistance will be given to all the orphans, material assistance to the most needy of them. To reach its ends this protective agency will secure that the orphans are as a rule left in their own families, and are entrusted, when these are non-existent or offer insufficient moral guarantees, to parents belonging to the colony or other colonists' families. The agency will promote the formation of special local committees. For its working expenses it disposes of: a) the eventual returns on its capital ; b) the annual contributions of its members ; c) subsidies ; d) eventual donations, legacies, temporary allo- cations and extraordinary income. The agency has the following catego- ries of members: a) ordinary members who engage for three years to pay at (i) Certain of the 69 protective agencies for the oq^hans of peasants killed in the war, al- ready formed in all the provinces of Italy, own a capital of more than 500,000 liras, accumulated bj^ means of contributions from the provinces, the communes, individuals and various corpora- tions ; and others have already ensured an annual budget of more than 50,000 liras. We sig- nalize the instance of Parma. Among the provinces Verona has already voted a budget for the orphans of 100,000 liras, Mantua one of 100,000 liras, Vicenza oneof 20,000 liras, etc. For the organization of the agencies for protecting the orphans of peasants killed in the war see an article by Alfredo F.^race in the Niiova Antologia, Rome, No. 1085, i April 191 7. (2) We would cite in particular the Colonia Agricola Provincialc del Foresta. This arose by the initiative of the provincial administration of Mantua which placed at the colony's disposal a holding of 37 hectares (i hectare = 2.47 acres), and a fund of 100,000 liras, which the communes and the local bodies were called upon to form. See in this connection Gli orfani contadini, the monthly bulletin of the Opera nazionale, Rome, no. 1,15 January 1917. Recently the Colonia Agticola \'icentina has also been formed with a capital of 514,000 liras arising partly out of unsolicited private contributions. See in this connection L'.4i,'/7'co^/Mra Vicentina, No. 2, 31 January 191 7. 112 >;OTICES RELATING TO AGRICUI.TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL least 10 liras a year ; b) perpetual members who make one payment of at least 100 liras ; c) members of merit who make an annual grant to the agency of at least 300 liras. The administration belongs to a directing council which has fifteen members. 4. A PROVINCIAL LABOUR OFFICE AT ROJME. • On 25 February 191 6 the provincial council of Rome resolved to insti- tute a pro^dncial labour office, and charged a special commisssion to draw up the necessary rules. These rules, which have been approved, define the following as the aims of the new office : the study of the various manifesta- tions of the economic, agricultural and industrial life of the province and the compilation of relevant statistics ; the study and regulation of the deplace- ment of the rural population with a view to facilitating the allocation of labour ; the observation, in the interest of labour, of the phenomena of labour and relative legislative measures, with a view to taking any action which may be demanded ; tlie study of the conditions of hygiene enjoyed by the labouring classes, both urban and rural, with a view to promoting measures fitted to combat the diseases which attack them ; co-operation in the progressive improvement of labour, technical and economic, and encouragement of the adoption of contracts better fitted to the special con- ditions of the different districts ; conciliatory action when controversies arise between employers and labourers, especially where iisi civici are con- cerned, and interv^ention by arbitration at the request of the conflicting par- ties ; the promotion of direct grants of land for cultivation ; vigilance for the observation and application of laws for improvements ; and finally vigilance for the observation of labour legislation. In exercising its functions this office will co-ordinate its efforts with those of the National Office and the Communal Office of Labour. RUSSIA. I. GOVERNMENT AID TO HOME INDUSTRY. npaBiiTe.ibCTBeHHMii B-fecTHiiKB (Gorernment Ma.'icna'^y) No. 231, 39 October-ii November 1916, Petrograd. Home industries, called in Russian Kustdrnoje proiswodstivo (KusT = shrub, bush), have spread chiefly over the middle and northern districts of the Russian kingdom, those governments namely of which the soil is not black earth — Moscow, Tvjer, Tula, Nishni^Novgord, Vjatka etc : — and are practised by the peasants either as accessories to farming or as independent callings. They include a whole series of different and numerous forms of production : woodwork and skilled woodcutting ; NOTICES REIvATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAI, II the production of linen, silk, laces and cotton ; the production of fur, leatherv\^ork, metalwork, the production of fanc}' articles, work in horn, potten,' etc. Present circumstances have brought certain of these industries more or less into the foreground and somewhat overshadowed others, thus ad- justing all of them to the present demands of the countr}-. The total value of the articles annually produced by home industry is about two thousand million roubles (i) and is therefore a very important element in Russian political economy. Home industry is in Russia as ancient as agriculture, but it became an object of State care onl}^ in the seventieth year of last century, when a special commission for its study was established in the Council of Trade and Industr5^ In 1888 the regulation of home industry was subjected to the supreme authority of the Ministry of the State Domains ; and in 1894 to that of the reorganized ]\Iinistr\' of Agriciilture, where a committee for home industry was called into being as part of the lately founded Section for Agriculture and Agricultural Statistics. This supreme authority is very notably sup- ported by the public corporations — the zemstvos, the agricultural societies and the local committees established in various places. The annual grants of the government to home industry have reached considerable sums of late years, as appears from the following figures : Year Roubles 1888 30,000 1903 100,000 1909 492,415 19^0 773,547 I9II 1,045,826 I916 2,429,699 For 1917 the Ministry of Agriculture is asked to give 2,459,734 rou- bles. The raising of the standard of the technique of production by home industry and its development form a constant aim : trade and industrial schools are founded ; large workshops are set up ; courses of instruction are given ; museums are established ; and exhibitions are held. In '1912 there were 120 such exhibitions. The admission to the all-Russian exhibi- tions held in Petrograd in 1902 and 1913 was of particular interest. The formation of co-operative societies for collective supply and marketing among those engaged in home industries, the Kiistari, is also forwarded by the Section for Agriculture and Agricultural Statistcs. In order to render possible the marketing of the products of home in- dustry abroad, a representative of the section was sent with specimens of these products to the United States at the end of 1915. Already orders (i) I rouble = about 2s. i ^Ind. at par. 114 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL have come- from America for articles of an artistic kind produced by home industry, and a connection has successfully been made with two large Amer- ican firms which have undertaken to market and to popularize goods so produced. In the spring of 1916 the section sent samples of them to the Lyons market, with most fruitful results. An important future market has thus been certainly secured. In the course of years an office of intelligence and information is to be established in Petrograd, where collections of samples and illustrated cat- alogues will be found, and where all the conditions of the trade and other information regarding home industry will be comnumicated to those inter- ested. It is also considered necessary to found in Paris a depository of specimen articles in which direct orders will be taken. Everything pro- mises that such a depository will have a practically certain commercial success. The experience gained in Paris will lead to the formation of a scien- tifically organized market in England, in which only the articles for which there is a demand will be supplied. So soon as this organization of markets begins to develop on the right lines, indicated by the government depart- ment, the supreme authority will leave the further conduct of the enter- prise to the zemstvos, who will develop still more the market for the arti- cles produced and trace new paths for home industry. 2. THE SETTIyEMENT OF KIRGHIZ NOMADS ON THE STEPPES OF TURKESTAN. — HaBtcTiH SoMCKaro (JrAiiaa {Bulletin of the Division of the Zemstvos), No. 10, Octo- ber, 19 1 6, Petrograd. Since the colonization of districts of Central Asia with settlers from European Russia has progressed, and railways have ensured the country's economic development, the Kirghiz — once the sole inhabitants of the vast regions of Turkestan — have little by little begun to abandon their nomadic life and settle down on the soil. Migration having been rendered more difficult by the establishment of the Russian colonies, the Kirghiz learnt how to till and cultivate tlie soil from the colonists and were converted to faith in the advantages of agriculture. First owners of tents and then whole villages asked the au- thorities to assign to them in full ownership clearly determined lots of agri- cultural land, to be held by the same legal forms as those of the Russian colonists. Consequently in igo8 the Council of Ministers decided to orga- nize the lands to be colonized in Turkestan so that they might be available not only for Russian colonists but also for the Kirghiz, and to give equal rights to ±he two peoples. This measure was at first adopted only in the district of Cokcetav.sc in the province of Acmolinsc, but its application was extended on 8 June 1909 to the other provinces of Turkestan. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL. ECONOMY IN GENERAL II5 The lots were allocated b}^ a special office within the Mnistry of Agri- culture and b}' temporary commissions on which the leaders of the peasants and of the Kirghiz were represented. A grant to one man might not be of more than fifteen deciatines (i) of land admitting of cultivation. 734 allotments had been made on 31 December 1915 of a total area of 3,350,226 deciatines, of which 2,133,338 deciatines admitted of cultivation. On the land so granted 174,363 Kirghiz men — or 8 per cent, of the male Kirghiz nomad population — had been settled. SWEDEN. THE AGRICULTURAL LABOUR SUPPLY IN 1915. -— Sverigcs Officiella StaUstik: Arbe- tartillgdng, atbctsiid och arbdslon inoni Sveriges jadbruk dr 1915 (Swedish Official Stati- stics : The Labour Supplj^ in relation to the Need and Duration of Work and to Wages in Swedish Agriculture in 191 5) Stockholm, 191 6. The official enquiry as to the relation between the labour supply, and wages and the duration of the working day in Swedish agriculture in 1915 followed the same plan as in 1914, and made use of similar docu- ments, namely fairly detailed forms of questions which were filled up by the }/residents of communal assemblies in 2,206 rural communes, that is in 94.4 per cent, of those comprised by the enquiry. The first question on these forms concerned the proportions of the labour suppl}^ in each rural commune. The answer should have been a general estimate, and should have indicated whether the agricultural la- /ourers domiciled in the place, or returning to it regularly, would ensure /sufficient labour for all the coming agricultural operations. The material collected shows that in 194 of the communes making returns, that is in 8.8 percent, of them, the labour supply was good, in 1,485 or 67.3 per cent, of them it was sufficient and in 513 or 23.3 per cent, insufficient, while 14 or 0.6 per cent of them thought themselves unable to answer with cer- tainty. As compared with those of the previous year these figures show a slight diminution in the proportions of the labour-supply — evidently due to the fact that the industrial depression produced after the outbreak of war in the autumn of 1914, which caused the supply of labour on the agricultural market to be abundant, has, it seems, gradually ceased to be felt. The proportions of the labour supply in the various districts were very different. But the figures which indicate the number of communes in the different departments in which the labour supply was inadequate do not allow certain conclusions to be made as to the greater or less number of labourers in each department in relation to the cultivated area. What is abo\-e all reflected in these figures is the greater or less progress of agricultural organization in -different places, and the greater or less abil- (i) I deciatinc — 2.69 acres. Il6 NOTICES RELATI^:G to AGRlCUIvTURAI, ECONOMY IN G ENERAi itj' of the employers to reduce work by using machinery and means of transport, and to make shift with the labour at their disposal by gener- alh" economical farming. The information given as to the hours and division of labour concerns onh* the working-day in agriculture proper, that is to say field-work, work in barns and on threshing-floors., etc. ; and does not appl}" to persons tending beasts, who have a considerably longer working day, chiefly pass- ed in stables and byres. Further as regards agriculture proper the figures supplied concern onl}' the hours of work in summer, this word being taken in the question- form- to cover the full agricultural season, that is the three summer months in which labour generall}' begins earliest and ends latest. As the days shorten the duration of the agricultural working day graduall}- lessens until it has come to be less by several hours than in summer. The gross average length of a summer working-day in the whole country, that is to say the day including inter\'als for rest, is twelve hours and a half ; that of the intervals is two hours and twelve minutes ; and the average net working day is therefore one of ten hours and eighteen minutes. During the five 3'ears during which enquiries as to agricultural labourers have been made, it has been impossible to ascertain what changes in these conditions are due to the whole organization of agricultural labour and therefore more or less constant. The duration and di^dsion of labour differ in the various parts of the country. If its net duration be principally considered it is seen that there are in Sweden three zones in which this is less than or equal to the average ascertained for the whole country- ; the zone, namely, which comprises the three departments {Idn) of Southern Sweden and the department of Kalmar, the zone formed by the departments of Gothemburg and Bohus, and that which comprises the large district of Central Sweden, extending inclusively from the department of Kopparberg to that of East Gothland. In the rest of the country the working day is relatively long. The usual price of labour differs much with districts. Taking the country as a whole, however, the case, is as follows : As regards the class of labourers most important to agriculture on a small scale — unmarried men and women permanently employed — the paATnent consists in annual mone}^ wages and food and lodging. The amount of these several forms of renumeration varies greatly with districts but the average for the whole country of the annual wage of a ser\'ing man is 343 crowns (i) in money, liis food is valued at 412 crowns or 1.13 crowds a day, and his total wage is therefore 755 crowns a 3'ear. For a woman the correspondent averages are 212 crowns, 335 crowns (0.92 crowns a da3') and 547 crowns. Especial^ in Norrand clothes are also given and their value is sometimes considerable. Labourers who are generallj- married, and who under the name of stature (agricultural labourers receiving mixed wages) work on the large (i) I Swedish crowu of gold = about i s. i ^|^d. at par. NOTICES REI^ATING I,0 AGRICUI^TURAI^ ECONOMY IN GENERAI, II7 properties in the agricultural districts properly so-called, receive, in ad- dition to their annual wages averaging 346 crowns, a payment in kind call- ed stat, which consists of milk, corn, potatoes, etc., and they are lodged together with their families ; so that the average return they receive for their work is 883 crowns a 3'ear, according to the estimate of those who have furnished these data. The figure comprises the value of a free cot- tage, which in South Sweden generally has two rooms and a kitchen and in the rest of the country a single room. The average vahie of such lodging is estimated at 68 crowns and that of free fuel at 53 crowns. These data do not hovever concern the ordinary ploughmen. The labourers who tend live stock receive larger money wages and sometimes also larger wages in kind, so that their annual earnings are placed at 939 crowns. Besides these labourers receiving mixed wages {stature) there are jour- neymen workmen permanently employed, who are paid entirel}^ or al- most entirely in money and whose daily wage varies much with districts. Its average amount is 2.72 crowns in summer and 2.07 crowns in winter, but is less by the average sums of 0.84 crowns and 0.76 crowns in these respective seasons, if the workman be fed by his employer. Besides these journeymen workmen, habitually engaged for a year or at least for six months by one employer, there are agricultural labourers who take work now for one and now for another, according to the needs of the moment. In summer the daily wage of one of these casual labourers averages 3.13 crowns, in winter 2.34 crowns, if he find his own food. If he be fed by his employer he is paid on an average 2.18 crowns in summer and 1.55 crowns in winter. Among the workpeople paid by the day there are also a large num- ber of women, who help in beetroot and potato-growing, in the hay and corn harvest, etc. They receive on an average 1.7 1 crowns for a summer day's work, or 1.16 crowns with food, if they are considered as part of the farm's fixed staff. For casual work they receive a little more, namely on an average for the whole country 1.87 crowns without and 1.29 crowns with food. In the winter months their wages diminish markedly as do also those of the men in the same category. A general comparison between wages in 1915 and in the years from 1911 to 1914 — if men tending live stock and receiving mixed wages, whose pay owing to their remuneration in kind remains almost stationar3^ be excepted — shows that wages of agricultural labourers of all categories increased by from 3.3 to 6.5 per cent, in 1914-1915, by from 5.2 to 10. i per cent, in the years from 1913 to 1915 and by from 10.2 to 18. i per cent, in those from 1911 to 1915. The increase seems to have been particularly marked in the case of the journeymen and the women employed ])erma- nently. On the other hand if total remuneration in money and kind be considered the greatest increase is seen to have been in the case of the la- bourers receiving mixed wages [stature) and the other agricultural labotir- ers who are paid chiefly in products in kind, for the price of most provi- sions has risen considerably owing to the international crisis. Thus in 1914-1915 the value of wages in kind rose by about 13 per cent, and Il8 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL from 1913 to 1915 by 37 per cent, which makes the increase in the value of the total wages of the stature labourers 9 per cent in 1914-1915 and 23 per cent, from 1913 to 1915. Compared therefore with the journeymen or with industrial workers they were much better paid than in the pre- vious year. UNITED STATEvS. LAND vSETTLEMENT IN CALIFORNIA. The progress of land settlement in California is revealed by a report lately rendered by the ComiTiission on I,and Colonization and Rural Credits. CaHfornia has had no State land policy. The subdivision of land for settlers, the character of the settlers, the kind of agriculture and the con- ditions of purchase of land have all been left to unregulated private enter- prise. There has been neither public control of the selection of coloni.sts, to insure their being effective agents of rural development, nor public scru- tiny of the soil and conditions of purchase, to render it certain that colonists find an opportunity rather than a temptation. The State has an immense area of fertile and unpeopled land, only 11,000,000 acres out of the 28,000,000 acres of farm land being cultivated. Yet comparatively^ few settlers are going to the country and many who have arrived in recent years have left. Neither costly advertising nor still more costly personal solicitation has served to attract colonists. Pro- gress in the country has not kept pace with progress in the towns ; for in the five years from 1910 to 1915 the gain in population of Californian cities and towns was three times that of the countr3\ The principal causes of the arrested development seem to be the high prices of land, the high rates of interest and the short terms for payment given in colonization contracts. Under these contracts it is practically impossible to earn the money required to pay for a farm in the time usually given. Many also complain that opportunities have been so exaggerated and the expenses of developing a farm so minimized, that settlers have been induced to undertake what on trial has proved to be impossible. It is to the interest of the whole State that its fertile lands should be cultivated and active colonization promoted. A large share of the meat consumed and many other farm products are now bought abroad ; and in- creased production would lessen the cost of living and keep at home money now sent out of the country to pay for food. Moreover the great proper- ties which are owned by non-residents and cultivated by tenants or by nomadic and unsatisfactory hired labour ought to be subdivided and culti- vated by residents. From statistics furnished by the tax commissioner it appears that 310 landed proprietors own over 4,000,000 acres of land suitable to intensive cultivation and capable of supporting a dense popu- lation. This land would make 10,000 forty-acre farms. One firm owns NOTICES REI,ATING TO AGRICUI^TURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL IIQ nearly i, 000,000 acres ; one railroad owns 500,000 acres ; in Kern county 1,000,000 acres — or more than half all the land in private ownership — are owned by four companies. The evils of such ownership are every year becoming more apparent. At one end of the social scale there are a few rich men who as a rule do not live on their estates, at the other a shif- ting body of farm labourers or a farm tenantr}-, made up largely of aliens and taking small interest in the progress of the communit3^ The interests of political stability, of agriculture and of society require that this inheri- tance from a Mexican land system and from former land laws of the United vStates be abolished. In California settlers have to pay for farms in periods of from three to ten years, while in other countries periods of from thirty to seventy-five years have been found necessary. Consequently a settler without a large cash capital or some income from another source has not been able to buy a farm. The Commissioners did not discover a single instance of a settler who brought with him only the limited capital required by State systems in other countries and was able to pay for his land within the time agreed upon in his contract. The experience of practical^ every colonization company, no matter how successful, has been that it would have been better for both the set- tler and the company if the original enterprise had been organized on a fi- nancial basis giving the settler more money for improvements and a longer time in which to pay for his farm. Dealers in real estate flocked from the overdone and less profitable fields of the Middle West, not to develop agriculture in California but to exploit it. It was the paradise of the boomer because it stands alone as regards rural advantages and attractions : in no other State can such a wide range of products or so many highly priced products be grown ; no other State affords the farmer or fruit grower an equal opportunity to exer- cise intelligence and scientific knowledge in planning his work. But more is necessary for good results than a subdivision of farms and an inflation of land prices. Not every man is suited to becoming an orange grower or has the habits of careful thoroughness needed in intensive agricul- ture of any kind. To create communities like P.edlands in th^ south or the Santa Clara Valley in the north workers of superior intelligence are requir- ed. If they be not already trained they must be willing to undergo ap- prenticeship in a most exacting form of agriculture which makes far great- er demands on knowledge and skill than do the fertile corn and wheat growing States of the Middle West. The best results in California can only be secured when colonization is carried out in accordance with carefully thought out plans, aimed at the creation of a definite form of agriculture or horticulture. This fact was not recognized b}' the speculative colonizing agent, who gave no more thought to the welfare of the community or the ultimate results of his en- terprise than he would have done had he been buying or selling grain or coal. Land was to him merchandise to be bought at the cheapest price and sold for as much money as the settler could be induced to pay. 120 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Relatively few of the men engaged in this business were knowingly dishonest but the majority of them were unthinking and ignorant. They did not know, and apparently did not care to know, how settlers were to obtain mone}' to improve and equip the farms sold to them or how they were to earn a living income. The prosperity of the settler was his own affair. The land agent's business was to make money out of him rather than to make money for him. An instance of the extent to which the land agent inflated prices is the case of a wheat ranch which was bought for seven dollars an acre. The buyer organized a syndicate composed of himself and his typist to which he sold the land for § loo an acre. Then as a syndicate he subdivided it and sold it to settlers for S 200 an acre. No settler who paid this outra- geous price could earn either its amount or the interest on it out of the soil. Yet sales of this character were made with ease. In part this was due to the fact that many of the buyers were also speculators. The}' were given evidence that land bought for seven dollars an acre was selling for § 200 an acre ; the prediction was made — and did not seem incredible — that next year it would sell for S 400 an acre. The air was full of stories of the mil- lions made b}'' subdividing land. This speculative colonization, which began about 1900 and culmina- ted about fifteen years later, has now run its course. It worked infinite harm to many honest and industrious but over-sanguine and credulous set- tlers. It interrupted and changed the conservative and successful develop- ment which was in process when it began. It has enabled non-resident speculators to take away from the State millions of dollars as the profits of the unwarranted inflation of prices ; and it has caused or will cause anx- iety and heavy losses to man}^ landowners who depend on the paying off of mortgages b)^ settlers having neither capital nor experience. A legacy of high land prices has been left to the State ; and it threatens to be a heavy economic burden, for practical and experienced farmers wiU not come to California if land of equal productive value in other States be cheaper. RUGGERI ALFREDO, gerente responsabile (c) Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases. I, i,E Service de Protection contrb les maladies des plantes et lks INSECTES NTJisiBLES DANS LES DIVERS PAYS (The Present Organization of the Ser^'ices for the Control of Plant Diseases and Insect Pests in the Different Countries). (19141 35o pages, 4to) Pn. ^00 a. Production et consommation des Engrais Chimiqubs dans le mondb (Production and Consumption of Chemical Manures in the World). (Second Edition, 1914, 162 pages, 5 diagrams, 2 maps, i6mo) 3.50 3. I«A lutte contre les sauterelles dans les divers PAYS(The Campaign against l^ocusts in Various Regions) (1916, 188 pages, i6mo) • . 3.50 {d) Publications of the Bureau of Economic and Social Intelligence, i( Iy'AcnviT6 DE l'Institut International d' Agriculture dans le Do- MAINE DE LA COOPERATION, DE L'ASSURANCE ET DU CRi:DIT AGRICOLES (The Work of the International Institute of Agriculture in the Field of Agricultural Co-operation, Insurance and Credit). (In French, German and Italian). (1912, 34 pages, i6mo) 1 0.50 a. Monographs on Agricultural Co-operation in Various Countries, Vol. I. (1911, 451 pages, i6mo). (In English and French) • 3,50 Do. Vol. II. (1915, 213 pages i6mo). (In English and French) ... • 3.50 3, An outline of the European Co-operative Credit Systems (Second Edition, 1913, 72 pages, i6mo) 1 0.50 4, I, 'Organisation de la statistique de la cooperation agricole dans quelques p.\ys (The Organization of the Statistics of .Agricultural Co- operation in Certain Countries). (1911, 163 pages, 8vo) 1.50 5. I,'assurance-gr£le dans quelques pays et ses problEmes (Insurance against Hail in Some Countries and its Problems). (1911, no pages, 8vo) . . • 1.50 6. Agricultural Credit and Co-operation in Italy: Short Guide to Rural Co-operation in Italy (in English, 35 pages and in Italian. 34 pages, i6mo) • 0.25 (e) Other publications. I . Iv'iNSTiTUT International d'Agriculture, son organisation, son Acriviift, sesrEsultats (The International Institute of Agriculture, its Organization, Activity, and Results). (1914, 31 pages, in English, French and Italian; illustr.) Frs. i — i. I,oots-Dop : L,E Present et l'Avenir de l'Institut International d'Agriculture (Conference) (Present and Future of the International Institute of Agriculture) (Address). (1912, 60 pages, i6mo) • i — 3. Santiago Aldunate : El Instituto Internacional de AGricultura y SU IMPORTANCIA PARA LA AmErICA lyATINA, EN ESPECIAL PARA CHILE (COU- ferencia) (The International Institute of Agriculture and its Importance for I88i " .Namely ^ ;E;xpenditure 1,478,106 Tiurnover 6,205,930 The inspectorate of dairies was obliged on the other hand to confine its action to the provinces of Antwerp, Brabant and Limbourg, in which seventy-eight co-operative societies are at work, only seven having interrupt- ed their activity since the opening of hostiUties. A certain slackening of business, due to the diminution in membership and also in the number of cows and the quantity of milk dealt with, has however been noted. Thus in the sixty-one dairies, as to which it has been possible to obtain precise data, the number of members is said to have been lowered by 10 per cent, and that of registered animals by 16 per cent, since 1913. The cows have moreover given less milk, a natural consequence of the famine in concentrat- ed foods. Therefore while in 1913 the average quantity of milk suppUed daily was 7.165 kilogrammes a cow in 1915 it was 5.910 kilogranmies, giv- ing a decrease of [18 per cent. Nevertheless 29,108,440 kilogrammes were dealt with in the dairies visited and 1,024,074 kilogrammes of butter manufactured. One of the association's most active branches has been indisputably the Central Credit Fund. The year 1915 was, says the report, one of the most important years it has had since its foundation. Not only was the number of affiliated local funds increased by forty-four but the savings deposits were more numerous than ever and hundreds of new small loans were made to cultivators in needy circumstances. Of 821 rural funds existing in Belgium at the end of 1915, 437 were affiliated to the central fund. At this date the number of the latter's subscribed shares was 8,987, ha\4ng increased by 420 since the preceding year. The capital in shares was thus brought up to 8,987,000 francs. The funds circulated in the year amounted to 63,009,921 francs, thus considerably surpassing their ordinary level. Twenty-one new credit accounts were opened for affihated funds, the total credit thus accorded being for 363,550 francs, which brought the amount of the credit in force on 31 December 1915 to 4,904,450 francs. The total of the savings deposits was 22,723,841 francs, having increased by 6,202,311 francs since 1914 and by 6,613,469 since 1913, the last normal year. " This considerable increase in the amount of savings deposits in the second year of the war is partly explained by the fact that cultivators have had partiall}^ to realize their invested capital. It was impo.ssible for them to procure the desired quantities of manures for their fields and of concen- trated food for their live stock. Thanks to the reserv^es of fertilizing sub- stances preserved in the soil they had generally verj' satisfactory'' harvests, and therefore had more liquid cash in hand than usual, but this was to the detriment of the wealth of the soil. They fed their live stock as the}^ could, having no choice but to avoid the expense of purchasing the concentrated THE ACTIVITY OF THK BEI.GIAN ' BOERENBOND foods usually on the market ; but the value of their stock was diminished in consequence, and the animals of which they got rid were seldom or ne- ver replaced. Analogous circumstances ruled in other branches of their farming. In a word husbandmen disposed of relative^ large sums of money but the fact was not always advantageous to them. What were they to do with these savings? Where could they invest them well, when banks and financial estabUshments were constantly lower- ing their rate of interest, and were as much as possible avoiding the accept- ance of payments, owing to the superabundance of money ? The husband- men turned to the savings and credit funds. These enjoyed their confi- dence, and were able further, because they were afiiliated to the central fund, to continue to pay interest at the rate of 3 per cent., which was in existing circumstances extraordinarily profitable for the deposits in question. It goes v\ithout sa3dng that the fund was obliged, in order to continue these terms, to be very circumspect and to be guided not by desire for gain but by a wish to render service to the husbandmen ". lyoans on land numbered twenty-seven and were of a total sum of 115,400 francs. There is further a new system of loans, particularly^ ad- vantageous to the husbandmen precariously situated owing to present circumstances, and known as small credit, and it gave excellent resiilts. It is as follows : " A loan may not surpass 600 francs and is repayable in annual in- talments in five years, unless the borrower formally express a desire to have this term extended to seven years, in which case he is held, during the first two years, only to the payment of the interest, which is at the rate of 2 per cent, a year. " If as a consequence of the war the object bought with the borrowed money is destroyed wholly or partially, the debt is remitted pro rata, ac- cording to the loss incurred, but the borrower must prove the loss. " He must find a third person as his surety. " Loans are granted to coimtrypeople in needy circumstances, espe- cially such as have suft'ered loss by the war. At first these conditions were interpreted fairly liberally, but later loans were made exclu.sively to per- sons within the following categories : 1. Husbandmen who have incurred certain definite losses by the war and the famiUes deprived of their support. 2. Husbandmen and workmen ctiltivating land and having suffered a reduction, due to the war, of such external resources as wages. " The borrowed money must serve an agricultural purpose, that is to say the purchase of live stock, small agricultural requisites, seeds, ma- nures, etc. " lyoans are made by the medium of the local savings and credit fund or, failing it, through a committee of three or four persons duly approved by the central fund. " On 31 December 1915 about forty of these loan committees were active. BELGIUM - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION " Funds and commitees become liable for per cent, of all losses 20 ^ eventually suffered by the central fund from the loans they make. The new service of credit, thus organized, met at once with great fa- vour which is proof of the extent to which it supplied a real need. At the end of the year the number of these small war loans had reached 2,561 and their total value was 1,262,045 francs. The greatest niimber were granted in the province of Brabant where 926,020 francs were advan- ced to small cultivators who had suffered particularly. The various insurance and mutual aid organizations continued to do business represented by a very respectable figure. Fire and life insurance and insurance against hail and mortality among live stock perceptibly increased the number of their policies, the amount of the premiums they received and the capital they insured. DENMARK. THE ACTIVITY OF THE ROYAI, SOCIETY OF DANISH AGRICUI^TURE IN 1915-1916. SOURCE: Aarsberetning om det Kon'gelige Danske I' year he must send the society a report on his activity. Normally the »State has no direct relations with the official responsible for consultations although he is a State functionary', but deals with him only through the medium of the society which superintends and pays him. An office of consultation has also been created in Russia. The official stationed there has those du- ties in relation to agriculture which fall in Italy to the commercial delegates abroad. This new office was created in 1914. It has aimed at encouraging the exchange of agricultural products and the means of agricultural production between Russia and Denmark, and making public in the two countries the general and special economic conditions of their agriculture, at SHbtuitting proposals tending to encourage such exchange to the ministry, at answering the relevant enquiries of public bodies and of individuals in the two States, and at counteracting in the Russian press all information which might be detrimental to Danish agriculture and its products. In 1915 the delegate undertook a long journey through all Russia in order to study the conditions most favourable to the sale of grain, which Denmark produces largely, and thus to supersede in this market Germany, hitherto almost a monopolist in respect of this article ol merchandise. A long account is published in the society's annual report of this jour- ney which had good results. The delegate succeeded in establishing com- m.ercial relations between Dani.sh producers and Russian consumers and in concluding numerous sales of seeds of vegetables, flowering plants and trees, of animals for reproduction and of agricultural machines. For pur- poses of jjropaganda the society has published two pamphlets on experience in cultivating plants in Denmark and on several noteworthy forms of Danish agriculture. The official responsible for the service of consultation trans- lated these into Russian and circulated them largely. As well as a series of articles in Rus.sian agricultural periodicals, which make Danish agricul- ture known, he has jjiublished others in Dnnish periodicals, and he has person- ally undertaken a large propaganda for the dissemination of knowledge of the conditions of Russian agriculture. Thanks to all these efforts, and in spite of obstjjcles raised by the war, many Danish producers have been able to find a footing in Russia and establish with this country sure relations which will soon vield excellent results. THE ACTIVITY OF THE ROYAI. SOCIETY 1 3 * * * The society's activity in the matter of agricultural education is very interesting. Places for study are of three kinds: they are on large farms, on small farms and on farms specially devoted to stock breeding. The education on the first of these lasts three years, each year spent on a different farm in order that the student may have a large and varied ex- perience. His instruction is essentially practical, but the society also en- courages theoretical knowledge, sending to each student a certain number of scientific manuals which remain his property after he has finally and suc- cessfully passed his examinations. In order to obtain a jDlace a student must be seventeen years old and must already have followed a two years' elementary course in agriculture. The students receive from 150 to 250 crowns a year ; they are lodged and kept and are regarded as in the employ- ment of the owner of the farm. They must enter the work the}- execute in a diarj- and cannot otherwise obtain a final certificate. In 1915 fiftj^-eight of these places were assigned and sixteen certificates of completed studies were awarded. Places for study on small farms are granted for two years. In addition to board and lodging the students receive from the owner 175 crowns in the first and 200 crowns in the second year. Bursaries for stock-keeping always last for three years which are spent on two different farms. The owner boards and lodges the students, and pays them 175 crowns in the first, 200 crowns in the second and 250 crowns in the third year. They must do all the work they are ordered to do, learn- ing especially to milk, to understand forage, to clean and care for animals, to kill pigs and to perform kindred tasks. * * * A very important share of the society's activity is devoted to scien- tific publications and methods of propaganda. In 1915 it published : the periodical " Tidsskrift fur I.andekonomie " {Review of AgriatUnral Economy) ; 2,400 copies of its annual report ; 1600 co- pies of the " Landekonomisk Aarburg 1916 " {Agricultural Yearbook 1916) and various less important matter. In order to circulate this literature of agriculture the publications were sent to 960 circulating libraries, many popular schools, the best elementary schoolmasters, and all the Sold.iterhyeni (Soldiers' Homes) depending on the Ministry of War. Moreover six lectiires on various agricultural subjects were held in January, February and March. The society has distributed a certain number of silver cups to agricul- tiirists who have particularly distinguished themselves by transforming, by indefatigable labour almost imaided by financial resources, uncultivated land into small properties having a high yield ; and has also given twenty medals to peasants and labourers, both men and women, who have shown particular skill in certain branches of the agricultural industry' or who have 14 DENMARK - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION seived their masters long and faithfully. Other prizes and medals, arising out of legacies to the society by various benefactors for determined objects, have also been awarded, and two competitions, to which prizes attach, for publications on seed-drying and horse-breeding, have been opened, f^^l^ The society has a special fund of about 25,000 crowns intended^for grants to poor students who have to pass examinations in agriculture at the Higher School of Agrictdture and the Veterinary School. Monthly grants of no more than 20 crowns are made for the maximum period of a year. Six students received in 1915-1916 such grants amounting altogether to about 900 crowns. * * * Mention should finally be made of four meetings, held on the initia- tive of the Society of Agriculture, by its representatives and those of three other large agricultural associations in the kingdom, namely the Associa- tion of Mutual Agricultural Societies, the Federation of Co-operative Socie- ties, and the Peasants' Association {Husnuind). At the first meetings no more was done than amply to discuss and to vote on an order of the day ad- dressed to the Minister of the Interior. This expressed a wish that agri- culture should be more largely represented in the commissions responsible for fixing the prices of foodstuffs. At the other meetings various other sub- jects were discussed, such as the employment of agricultural machines, the protection of agricultural interests abroad, the formation of an agricultural office of accounts. All the meetings were well attended and their results have been very important to agriculture. Summary accounts of their discussions have been published in differerent agricultural reviews. GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND. THE AGRICUIvTURAI. ORGANIZATION SOCIETY IN ENGlvAND AND WAIVES. source: Thj-: Report of the AGRicin-TURAL Organization Society for the year ended March 31st, igi6. I^ondon, The Stepney Press, 1916. § I. Introduction. The Agricultural Organization Society was founded in 1901 for the purpose of advancing co-operation among English and Welsh farmers. Its work is of a twofold character : i) It is a propagandist body — as such it seeks to spread the co- operative principle and helps in the formation of new societies. 2) It is an organizing body and as such advises and helps the socie- ties already formed. The co-operative societies with which it concerns itself may have one or more of the foil sowing objects : i) They may buy for their members manures, seeds, feeding stuffs, implements and other articles, securing their purity and obtaining whole- sale terms from the manufacturers, importers or wholesale merchants. 2) They ma}^ help to market produce : a) by organizing the milk supply on a co-operative basis, thus eliminating the middlemen's profits which lower the price to the producer and raise it to the consumer; b) by establishing co-operative butter and cheese factories in suitable districts ; c) by establishing co-operative depots for the collection of eggs; d) by grading and packing fruit in order to place it on the market in a fresh and attractive condition; e) by organizing the proper classing and packing of wool, thus securing a better price in the market for sheep breeders ; /) by organizing co-operative markets and by breaking down the rings formed against the producer ; g) by organizing the consignment of goods in bulk and arranging terms with railway companies and carriers, thus reducing the costs of transport. 3) They may hire or buy pedigree stallions, btdls or boars, for the use of their members at reasonable fees. 4) They may arrange for all kinds of agricultural insurance. l6 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 5) They may acquire land and let it to their members in small hold- ings and allotments. 6) They may establish agricidtural credit societies. Co-operative societies having these objects become affiliated to the Agricultural Organization Society on applying for membership and on paying a small subscription. They continue to be entirely self-supporting and self-governed but affiliation brings them many benefits. It enables them to receive copies of model rules at their time of formation, to be ad- vised in matters of policy, to be helped with their book-keeping, and to be assisted in their negotiations with government departments, railway companies and others. The affiliated societies may avail themselves with- out payment of the services of the experts on the staff of the Agricul- tural Organization Society, whose special knowledge covers such subjects as dairy farming, eggs and poultry, wool, small holdings and allotments, accounts and the rules of co-operative societies. Finally all of them pro- fit by the fact that the parent society co-ordinates them. The parent society itself does no trade and makes no profit. For many years it was supported entirely by voluntary contributions, but it now also receives grants from the Development Fund in aid of its work for the general development of agricultural co-operation, and from the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries in aid of its promotion of co-operation in connection with small holdings and allotments. As regards its organization the society has offices in Westminster and * employs a general secretary. Its affairs are managed by thirty-two go- vernors who include three nominees of the Board of Agriculture; and two each of the County Councils' Association and the Co-operative Union. Seventeen further governors are elected by the affiliated societies and of this number one fourth retire each year in alphabetical rotation. The society divides its local work among eight branches which cover all England and Wales, having their respective offices at York, Preston, Derby, Tonbridge, Salisbury, Plymouth, Bangor and Brecon. § 2. General Review of the Work in 1915-1916. The war has created opportunities for the Agricultural Organization Society : first because the need for national economy and the interruption' of overseas trade have at last caused British agriculture to be recognized as a basic and essential industry ; and secondly because the scarcity of la- bour, the difficulties of transport and the novel conditions of the market have brought the farmer face to face with problems which have shaken his conservatism and made him turn to co-operation as a possible solution. It was therefore possible to extend the society's enterprise in several di- rections in 1915-1916. a) New Branches. Two of its eight branches were formed between i April 1915 and 31 March 1916. They are the North Midlands Branch, which covers the THE AGRICULTURAL ORGANIZATION SOCIETY 1 7 counties of Nottingham, Stafford, Leicester, Derby and Rutland and has its offices at Derb}^ ; and the South Western Branch, for Devon and Corn- wall, wliich has its offices at Plj'mouth. b) New Soieties. In the same period forty new societies were affiliated to the Organi- zation Society. They are distributed as follows according to their objects Purchase of Agricultural Requirements .... 17 Dair>' 3 Eggs and Poultry 10 Auctions etc 2 Land Renting (Small holdings and allotments) . 5 Credit i Miscellaneous 2 40 The Board of Agriculture having drawn especial attention to the use- fulness of forming Village Food Societies, to increase the growing of vege- tables, encourage the cultivation of allotments and gardens, and bring any pieces of uncultivated land into cultivation, the society endeavoured with success to bring several of these into existence. In some instances the Womens' Institutes filled the part of Village Food Societies. . c) Women's Institutes. The Agricultural Education Conference on Agricultural Education for Women reported in favour of the formation of Women's Institutes which should stim_ulate a desire for rural education ; and at the annual meeting of the .Agricultural Organization Society in 1915-1916 a resolu- tion was accordingly passed recommending that the society should under- take the work of such formation. The services were secured of the lady who is secretarN' to the National Council of Women's Institutes of Canada, a country in which these institutions play an important part, and up to 31 March 1916 fourteen of them had been founded in England and Wales. It is their object " to study home economics, to provide a centre for educa- tional and social intercourse, to encourage home and local industries, to develop co-operative enterprises, and to stimulate interest in the agricul- tural industrj' ". d) The Supply of Produce to the Army. The system under which the military camps obtained tlieir supplies of fruit and vegetables was often unsatisfactory, the different units compet- ing with each other so that prices rose while quality frequently remained indifferent. In October 1915 the Agricultural Organization Society toge- ther with the Purchasing Officer of the 68th Division, stationed at Bed- ford, formulated a scheme for purchasing the Division's whole supply in bulk ; and this was approved by the General Officer Commanding and was l8 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - COrOPERATION AND ASSOCIATION at once put in force. The society's expert in fruit and market garden pro- duce was placed at the disposal of the military authorities, as adviser. The result was a rapid improvement in the qualit}'' of the supply, an econo- my to the military authorities, better prices for the producers who profited by the elimination of the middleman, and cheaper fruit and vegetables for the civihan population since general prices fell with army prices. The matter was brought to the attention of the War Office and the Army Coun- cil has in consequence approved the gradual extension of the scheme to other camps. A new committee, called the Army Canteen Committee, has been formed to take over the powers and duties in respect of canteens hitherto entrusted to the Board of Control of Regimental Institutes ; and also a Command Canteen Committee for each command. The Agricultu- ral Organization Society is represented bj^ its nominee on the Army Can- teen Committee and on each of the Command Canteen Committees. The necessary' central purchasing body has been found in a new so- ciety affiliated to the Agricultural Organization Society, the Agricultural Produce Supplies, limited. The Agricultural Organization Society's late expert in fruit and market-garden produce is its secretary and manager. It distributes no profits, but charges a commission to cover management expenses and returns any surplus funds to the War Office. e) Relations with the County War Agricultural Committees and with other Bodies. In November 1915 the Board of Agriculture notified the County Wax Agicultural Committees that the societ}' had placed its services and those of its branches and organizers at their disposal ; and the society itself sent them a circular letter confirming this information and drawing their atten- tion to certain branches of agricultural work to which co-operation was particularly applicable. The subse(juent action varied in different counties : in some direct representation on the war agricultural committees has been given to the farmers' co-operative societies ; in some the Womens' Institutes have been recognized as District War Agricultural Committees ; in Glamorganshire the farmers' co-operative societies have been appointed to act as the Dis- trict War Agricultural Committees ; in Cornwall the countj^ committee or- ganized the supply of sulphate of ammonia through the Farmer's Central Trading Board which is affiliated to the Agricultural Organization Society. The society has also worked in close touch with the Scottish and Irish Agricultural Organization Societies, the Housing Organization Society, the Fisheries Organization Society and the Co-operative Union, and with County Councils. Agricultural Colleges and many other public associations. Its relations with the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries have been both harmonious and important. /) Publications. The society's monthly journal, Co-operation in Agriculture, has been suspended in the interests of economy. By arrangement with the pro- THE AGRICUI^TURAL ORGANIZATION SOCIETY 19 prietors of the Smallholder a column of that paper is however devoted ever}^ week to matter supplied by the society, and such columns are repro- duced every month and sent to all who formerly received Co-operation in Agricnlhire. A proposal to issue a quarter^ has been abandoned for the present ; but the society has inaugurated a series of booklets, each of which will deal with an important aspect of agricultural co-operation, and which will be published at a price sufficient only to cover the cost of printing. g) Finance. The following is a summarized account of the society's expenses in 1914-15 and 1915-1916 : T914-1915 1915-1916 Salaries & S D 6,098 9 10 2,022 I 3 1,100 2 10 725 8 2 1/2 265 16 2 1/2 229 5 6 104 4 3 & S D 6,420 14 9 2,839 18 I 1,147 10 2 1/2 574 6 10 1/2 327 0 3 57 II 0 337 8 10 131 18 II Travelling and maintenance of governors and others Rent and other expenses connected with office. Printing, duplicating, literature Postage, telegrams, telephone Audit fees of affiliated societies Egg or Poultry Demonstration Train . . . Other expenses Total . . . 10,545 8 I 11,836 8 II The society's income in the same two j-ears was as follows : 1914-1915 1915-1916 Subscriptions Donations Contributions from affiliated societies . , . Advertisements in Journal and Report . . . Sale of Journal or other literature .... Bank interest & S D 1,782 13 56 18 6 262 16 3 126 II 0 13 6 I 13 10 7 & S D 1 ,605 9 6 382 9 3 52 5 4 3 14 2 Total . . . 2,255 15 5 2,043 18 3 20 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The excess of expenditure over income was therefore £ 8,289 ^^s Sd in 1914-1915 and £ 9,792 los Sd in 1915-1916. These deficits were covered by government grants, as is seen in the published balance-sheets, here reproduced. Debit 1914-1915 1915-1916 Credit 1914-1915 1915-1016 Amount refunded to His Majesty's Treasury . . Excess of Expenditure over Income Balance £ S D 394 8 5 8,289 12 8 1,710 7 4 £ S D 1,710 7 4 9,792 10 8 183 9 4 Balance as per last Ba- lance-Shat Grants : Small Holdings Account . Development Fund . . . £ S D 394 8 5 2,000 0 0 8,000 0 0 £ S D 1,710 7 4 1,988 0 0 7,988 0 0 10,394 8 5 11,686 7 4 10.394 8 5 11,686 7 4 It is clear therefore that the Agricultural Organization Society is mainly supported by government subsidies. § 3. The Affiliated Societies. a) The Suciefies in General. The affiliated societies experienced in 1915-1916 a very general in- crease both in their membership and in the amount of their business, and this in spite of the impediment? to agriculture which are due tj the war — the scarcity- of labour, the difficulties of transport. The disturbance of the market has on the whole favoured the farmer ; he has had to pay more for certain of his requirements but the price of his produce has risen to a more than compensatory extent, and the creation of the armj'^ has provided a new and profitable demand for his supplies. The rise in prices has naturally increased the turnover of the societies, a fact which should be borne in mind in drawing conclusions from their balance-sheets. The total membership of the 550 aflBliated societies in the year under review was 55,831 and their total turnover was £3,428,960. Of this sum more than two thirds, namely £ 2,450,397, belonged to the societies for the purchase of agricultural requirements, most of whom sell farm produce as a secondary business. These societies numbered 213 and their combined membership was 26,241. The following table shows the comparative importance of the different groups of societies : THE AGRICULTURAI, ORGANIZATION SOCIETY 21 Class of Scxuety No. of Societies No. of Members Turnover Purchase of Agricultural Requirements Dairy Egg and Poultry Auction and Produce Small Holdings and Allotments .... Miscellaneous Credit 550 213 26,241 -2.450,397 38 4,086 722,620 29 2,996 87,954 27 2,029 140.363 177 15,975 12,434 18 3.563 15,192 48 941 — 55,831 3,428,960 The following are the ten counties in which the co-operative societies had a turnover running into six figures : County No. of Societies No. of Members Suffolk .... Yorkshire . . . Hampshire . . Carmarthen . . I^ncashire . . Cheshire. . . . Wiltshire . . . Gloucestershire. Essex lyondon .... 5 44 31 10 II 10 27 10 9 13 2,241 450,962 ^,985 373,618 4.741 246,161 3,650 245,030 1,467 232.552 2,385 231,892 2,221 192,412 1,309 158.865 503 158,117 3.704 129,388 The importance of co-operation in each of these counties except Glou- cestersliire is explained by the existence in it of one very strong society. In 1915-1916 a co-operative society for the purchase of agricultural imple- ments in each of the first six of them, and a co-operative dairy society in Wiltshire, in Essex and in London, had itself a turnover rurming into six figures. In Gloucestershire several societies of secondary importance were responsible for the large turnover. In the report of the parent society the affiliated societies are'^critici- zed for their frequent lack of sufficient working capital. " Hardly any 22 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION society has as much as it could usefully employ and in many progress is retarded because the management is hampered by want of money... The real necessity for it has not hitherto been fully realized. It is in truth extraordinary on what small capital some societies have built up large turn- overs.... The S3'stem of v^orking through central and branch depots is gain- ing more and more favour in the case both of trading and of produce so- cieties. For this and other reasons m.ore capital is desirable ". As a sup- plement to the issue of loans many societies find it convenient to invite loans from members, repayable at a certain notice and carrying regular interest. The societies do not aim at making large profits in order to pay divi- dends to their members, but generally prefer to return the benefits which accrue from co-operative purchase immediately, in the form of lower pri- ces, merely retaining a sufficient margin to secure against loss. However an increasing number of societies find themselves in a position at each year's end to grant members, as a bonus, a small sum in the pound on the goods sold. The system tends to increase both membership and the amount of business done. By a clause in the Finance Act (No. 2) 1915 excess profits are com- puted in the case of co-operative societies not on the basis of the total profit of a socictA^ but on that of the individual profit accruing to each member. This provision is most important, for the increased profits made by many societies since the war are entirely due to an increased membership. h) Small Holdings and Allotment Societies. As regards societies of this tj^pe progress is shown in the number that were formed during the year, but the total acreage they held and the num- ber of their tenants diminished. The reduction in acreage is probably due to the expiry- of leases and to the increased demand for small allot- ments, to be made into gardens by town workers. A considerable num- ber of new societies were formed for the purpose of acquiring land for such garden allotments, and most of these were registered in the latter part of • the year and had not yet acquired land when the report was made. The following comparative data should not therefore be taken as indicating anj- real retrogression. The figures for 1914, which are taken from the Board of Trade Labour Gazette are incomplete, since they con- cern only 147 societies whereas 172 were registered in that year by the Agricultural Organization Society. 1915-16 Number of Societies. )^ ') Members » » Tenants Acreage held. . . . 147 177 16,205 15.975 12,234 10,498 15432 14,646 THE AGRICULTURAIv ORGANIZATION SOCIETY 23 c) Agricultural Credit Societies. The forty-eight co-operative credit societies lent during the year the total sum of £ 1,087. ^^^^ is a very limited success and one which has little relation to the demand for credit : many farmers, small holders and others are seriously hampered because they cannot obtain temporary loans on easy terms. The Agricultural Organization »Society decided in 1915-1916 on an investigation into the causes of the slow progress of agri- cultural credit societies. d) The Agricultural and General Co-operative Insurance Society. This is the single insurance society affiliated to the Agricultural Or- ganization Society. The year 1915 showed an increase of 25 per cent, in its premium income and the gross sums insured against fire amounted to over £4,000,000. A 5 per cent, dividend was declared on shares and a bonus of 5 per cent, on life premiums. The net claims on account of fires were considerably higher than the average of recent years, so, although the society had worked at a profit, no bonus was declared to the holders of fire policies in accordance with the practice which has been such an inter- esting feature in the society's work since its formation. In consequence too of the unsettled state of the investment market, the investment re- serve fund was increased, and the balance remaining was carried forward. e) The Farmers' Central Trading Board. This board is a central wholesale establishment for all kinds of agri- cultural requirements and it receives applications for membership from societies affiliated to the Agricultural Organization Society. In 1915 it absorbed the Agricultural Co-operative Federation and its headquarters were then transferred to lyondon. It quickly became apparent that since many districts obtain their agricultural supplies from other ports than I/ondon some local organiza- tion would be useful. North- Western, North-Eastern and Welsh Sections of the board therefore came into being. The increase of sales in 1915 was satisfactory' and they promised to be yet more considerable in the following year. § 4. A Direction of Future Effort. The Agricultural Organization Society is especially desirous of pro- moting in England and Wales continuous crops and the co-operative ownership of farm implements. To this end Mr. T. Wibberley, who had had much experience of such work in Ireland, was sent on a lecture tour through the English and Welsh counties in the winter of 1915-1916. We quote from his report : " Undoubtedly in comparison with other English industries agricul- ture is in many places very backward, but the recognition of this fact by 24 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION those engaged in agriculture is the first essential step towards progress. As to the progress made and likely to be made, it was with pleasurable surprise that I found a number of farmers at practically every place I visited who, from the somewhat meagre writings which so far I have been able to put before the public on the subject, have during the past few years been growing continuous crops, on what they call a small scale and what we in Ireland would call a very large scale. From the information so obtained it is very evident that the system with adaptations is just as sui- table for English as for Irish conditions — in Wales and the south western districts of England even more suitable. " Again as regards the co-operative purchase and use of implements, the recent introduction of motor and motor implements into agricultural work has opened up a vast field for development in this direction on the part of the bigger farmer.';. On the other hand the spread of the vSmall Holdings Act calls for — even demands for the success of the Act — a far more extended use of modern machinery, which in the case of the smallholder must be purchased and used conjointly... Already several both large and small implement societies have been formed or are in the process of formation. There are difficulties in the way, the chief one being the extreme difficult}^ which some societies are meeting in the procuring of machinery - a difficulty which I have tried several times to fpcus at- tention upon, and one which it is to be hoped will shortly receive the se- rious attention of the authorities concerned ". MISCKlvIvANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO CO OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. GERMANY. SOME FACTS AS TO THE CO-OPERATIVE MOVEIVEENT IN GERMANY. — Jahrbuch des allgemeinen Verbatidcs der auf Selhsthilfe heruhenden deutschen Erwerbs- und Wirt- schaftsgenossenschafien e. v. fiir 1914. XVIII Jahtgang, Berlin, 1915. On I January 1915 there were 117 central and 36,032 ordinary co-ope- rative societies. More than half of these — 55.4 per cent. — were in Prus- sia. The number of central co-operative societies had not changed since i January 1914, but that of the others had increased by 1,006. All or almost all this increase dated however from the months before the war. The in- crease between i January and i August 1914 was one of 941 which is to say that between i August 1914 and i January 1915 it was only of 65. It should be noted that between i January and i August 1915 it was of 122. As compared with preceding years 1914 showed lessened progress, the increase having been 1369 in 1913, 1676 in 1912, and 1426 in 1911. The increase of 1006 in 1914 was not equally distributed among the various kinds of co-operative societies. It included 400 credit societies, 168 trade socie- ties, 199 societies for the purchase of primary materials, 116 breeding societies, 69 house-letting societies, 52 rural producers' societies, and no important number of any society of another kind. The total number of 36,032 co-operative societies was distributed as follows : 1. Credit societies 19.700 2. Societies for the purchase of the primary materials of industry' 846 3. Rural societies for the purchase of primary materials 3.167 4. Merchants'societies for the purchase of merchandise 306 5. Consumers' societies 2,418 6. Societies for the purchase of agricultural machines 22 7. Labour societies ^ 2,368 8. Producers'societies 4-555 9. Breeding societies 39^ 10. Societies for letting dwellings 1.538 11. Various societies 7^6 Total . . . 36,032 26 lNFORiL\TION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION As regards form of liability the societies were distributed as follows: 1. Unlimited liability societies . . . 21,849 or 60.6 per cent. 2. Societis to which new payments were unlimited 168 " 0.4 3. Limited liabiUt}^ societies - . . . 14,015 " 39 " " The unlimited Uabilit^- societies were diminishing while the percentage of societies having limited hability was increasing. In 1905, 68.8 per cent, of the societies had unlimited and only 30.6 limited liability. Unlimited liability prevailed in 1915 among the credit societies, 87 per cent, of which had this form, and among the rural producers' societies of which 65 per cent, had it. Limited HabiHty predominated on the other hand among all the others, especially among the trade societies, the merchants' societies and the producers' societies. ITALY. I. A MEETING OF THE REPRESENTATIVE^ OF THE CATHOLIC ECONOMIC OR- GANIZATIONS OF THE SOUTHERN PROVINCES. — Azione Sociale, organ of the Unione Economico-social e fra i cattolici iialiani, No. 17, Faenza, 15-31 December 1916. Under the auspices of the Economico-Social Union of Catholic Italians and on the initiative of Federazione Bancaria Italiana (i) in agreement with the Federazione Italiana delle Casse Riirali Cattoliche, a meeting of re- presentatives of the Catholic economic institutions of vSouthern Italy was recently held at Rome. Its object was to find practical means of inten- sifying Catholic economic activity' in the south. The organization and the present condition of the Catholic banks and the rural funds and agri- cultural union of the provinces of the district were examined, and discus- sions were held as to the methods best adapted to promote their develop- ment and co-ordination. As regarded, in particular, the banks, this meeting decided to entrust to the Federazione Bancaria Italiana the task of : a) promoting and bringing to a conclusion action for the formation of provin- cial or local institutions of credit in the most important centres ; h) facili- tating the transformation of existing banks from co-operative limited liability (i) This federation of Italian Catholic banks was formed at Milan " in order to afford reciprocal protection, \igilance, co-ordination and assistance to each bank in its autonomous exercise of economic activity ". The bank discharges the following fimctions by the means of a federal committee: a) it visits federated banks and causes their inspection at least once a year: h) it acts as an intermediary relating them mutuallj' in order to ensure that the activ-ity of each harmonizes with the collective interest; c) it endeavours to make them take opportune mea- sures for the avoidance and defeat of the moral and financial difficulties which they may en- counter ; d) it assists and represents the federated banks where their general interests are concerned. I^rFORMATION REI,ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 27 societies to simple limited liability societies, facilitating the desired increase of their capital ; c) helping these banks to perfect and complete the branches of their activity, actively relating the interests of the various Catholic institutions, etc. As regards rural funds we should state, as does the report, that in these provinces " there are numerous Cathohc rural funds but all of them do not fulfil the objects for which they were founded ". In order to intensify the movement it was therefore judged necessary to reinforce, co-ordinate and improve it. For the execution of this work of organization the Federa- zione delle Casse Ruyali Cattoliche of Bologna had long delegated the Cre- dito Centrah of Latium wliich, in view of the fact that it is an institution federating the Catholic economic institutions of the Roman and adjacent provinces, was particularly fitted for the task. The meeting noticed the action taken by the Credito Centrale of Latium, which promoted the forma- tion of provincial federations of the rural funds of Reggio in Calabria, Sa- lerno and Benevento, and, with a view to collaboration entered into rela- tion with those of Cosenza and Amatrice ; and which caused various re- unions to be held in other provinces. The meeting therefore confirmed the mandate of the Credito Centrale. It then decided : a) to work for the consti- tution of legally founded federating centres in regions where none exist, pref- erably in provincial capitals, and where this is impossible to make the strongest and best administered rural fund in a given zone its federating centre ; b) to cause all federations to correspond with the Credito Centrale of Latium which will act as their intermediary in their relations with the Federazione italiana delle casse rurali and afford them particular assistance in technical, legal and fiscal matters, f aciliting all their financial business ; c) to cause all CathoHc rural funds, in order that thej- may complete^ dis- charge their social and economic function, not only to afford cheap credit but also to facilitate active habits of thrift among the agricultural classes. Such action wiU place at their disposal a sufficient amount of deposits and thus allow them to be maintaned and to discharge their functions by means of local resources. If their resources prove insufficient the local federations ■will undertake to supplement them, taking all desirable precautions. There was question at the meeting of the organization of agricultural unions (Catholic societies for the purchase of article useful to agriculture). In the south there are very few of them (at Benevento, Campobasso, Std- mona, etc.) although they could very usefully assist the development of local agriculture. The meeting recognized their importance and deliber- ated concerning them, and then decided : a) to work for the constitution in legal form of agricultural unions, either provincial or regional, which ■would operate in centres where their influence is least strong and bring into being efficient societies for the protection of the moral and economic interests of agriculturists ; b) to take action causing these agricultural unions not to confine themselves to the collective purchase of merchandise and manures necessary to agriculture, but to undertake also the export of products of the soil, entering therefore with this object into relations with the Catholic agricultural unions of North Italy. For the execution 28 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION of this work the action of the national federation of agricultural unions, which has yet to be founded, will be necessary. It will undertake the formation at Rome of a special office for the needed work of propaganda. * 2. THE FEDERATIONS OF THE CATHOI^IC RURAl, FUNDS OF THE PROVINCES OF BOI^OGNA, REGGIO D'EMILIA, FORI, AND SAI^ERNO IN 1915-1916.— Coope- razione Popolare, nos 22-24. Parma, 31 decembrer 1916. We borrow from Cooperazione Popolare, the organ of the Catholic rural funds, the following data as to the position and activity of some pro- vincial federations of rural funds in 1915-1916. The Federazione delle Casse Ritrali e Popolari of the province of Bologna is one of the most im- portant Catholic federations of rural funds. A year ago it grouped 86 funds, 77 of them rural and g of them poptdar, which comprised altoge- ther 7,541 members. It now groups 88 funds, 78 of them rural and 10 of them popular, which have 7,617 members. We here resume the general position of the federated funds on 31 October 1914, 31 October 1915 and 31 October 1916 : On 31 October 1914 1915 1916 Federated funds 83 86 88 Number of members inscribed. 7>385 7>54i 7.617 Loans to members 1,870,065.74 1,810,060.95 1,581,904.68 Securities 573.565-73 708.682.33 1,067,237.34 Deposits on current credit ac- count 863,138.91 982,745.64 1,903.131.77 Assets in coin, merchandise and miscellaneous assets .... 198,864.90 221,646.68 336,088.39 Total. : . 3.5»5.635-28 3,723,135.60 4,888,362.18 Iviabilities in interest and costs for 10 months 106,660.98 110,691.64 130,208.02 Total. . . 3.612,296.26 2,833,827.24 5,018,570.20 Liabilities. Trust deposits 3,276,908.17 3,455,818.73 4,649,820.76 Current debit accounts .... 60,122.85 57,667.31 17,376.33 Interest not due and various liabilities 24,810.77 42,771.98 40,645.05 Total . . . 3,361,841.79 3,556,258.02 4,707,842.14 vSociety's capital 125,528.37 147,315.14 167,788.97 Total . . . 3,487,370.16 3.703,57316 4,875,631.11 Assets in interest and profits for 10 months 124,926.10 130,254.08 142,939.09 Total . . . 3,612,296.26 3,833,827.24 5,018,570.20 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATJON 29 This table shows above all a constant increase of deposits whidi is proof of the confidence felt in these institutions. Thus on 31 October 1914 deposits amounted only to some 3,277,000 liras, on 31 October 1915 to 3,456,000 liras, and on 31 October 1916 to 4,650,000 liras ; that is they increased by nearly 180,000 liras between 1914 and 1915, and by 1,200,000 liras or an average of 100,000 liras a month between 1915 and 1916. It should be remembered that this increase in deposits and the accom- panying reduction in loans are partly due to an abandonment, on account of the war, of much agricultural and even of commercial and industrial enterprise. We may therefore expect that at the end of the war, when life returns to its normal course, deposits will diminish and applications for loans, which have become insignificant, will increase. L,oans decreas- ed from about 1,870,000 liras on 31 October 1914 to 1,810,000 liras on 31 October 1915 and 1,582,000 liras on 31 October igi6. Thus the dimi- nution was one of nearly 60,000 liras between 1914 and 1915 and of 228,000 liras between 1915 and 1916. If this increase in deposits be added to the reduction of loans a total sum of about 1,700,000 liras is obtained. If secondary items in the account be left out this sum comes to be one of more than a million liras which went to swell that comprised under the heading " deposits on credit current accounts in credit institutions ", while nearly half a million liras was entered under the heading " securities ". As in preceding 3-ears the federation did not neglect to give assistance in technique, book-keeping and legal matters to the federated societies. The Federazione delle Casse Rurali of Reggio d'Emilia groups twenty- three rural funds. We take the following data from their balance-sheets for 31 December 1915. Capital and reserve 92,774.40 liras Trust deposits 2,183,476.25 » Bills held 1,279,414.11 » In general the ])osition of the rural funds in the province is good. The Federazione delle Casse Rurali of the province of Forli groups, according to the report presented by the presidents to the federal meeting on 8 June igi6, societies which are in an entirely satisfactory economic and financial position, in spite of the crisis due to the abnormal state of affairs. They were able in the year in question to afford the same credit to their members as in IQ15, but by a wise provision they gradually reduced their paper and then formed a reserve in the form of a credit current account at the Banca del Credito Romagnolo from which they receive a preferential rate. The diminution in their investments is due rather to the diminished demands of their members than to the imposition of restrictions. The recently formed funds are those which have most increased the sum of their deposits. The others faced an alternative of increase or di- minution, but increases prevailed at the end of the year, showing that 30 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPICRATION AND ASSOCIATION the war had notably reacted on those institutions which still enjo}^ popnlar confidence. The punctuality of members in repaying the amounts they borrowed has been entirely praiseworthy. Loans numbered 3,025 on 31 December 1914 and had risen to 3,114 at the end of 1915. Deposits on 31 December 1915 amounted to 854,800.49 liras as against 807,901.27 liras on 31 Decem- ber 1914 : that is they increased by 46,899.22 liras. This increase shows that even the poorest .classes, from whom the deposits emanated, were well-to-do, a fact confirmed by the diminution in loans which allowed the funds to augment their reserves in specie. The amount of the bills held was lowered from 840,450.35 liras in December 1914 to 720,809.17 liras at the end of December 1915. The Federation of Salerno was founded in April 1916. It immedi- ately undertook the formation of new funds in the vast region of Salerno and lyucania. The rural funds of Siano, Vietri-sul-Mare, Bracigliano, Castel San Giorgio, Toirello, Pastena and Fosaro were thus constituted, and others are in course of formation at Eboli, Danzara, Cioriani, Fisciano, S. Cipriano Picentino and Agliara. 3. THE INSPECTING AND BOOK-KEEPING OFFICES FOR CO-OPERATIVE SOCI- ETIES. — IsHtuto di credito per le cooperative. Branch at Reggio d'Emilia. Extract from the report on the balance-sheet for 1916. The Istituto di credito per le cooperative of Milan founded long since and most opportunely offices for the inspection and book-keeping of co-op- erative societies. The reason for their existence is explained as follows in the report on the budget for 1916 of the Reggio d'Emilia branch. " The needs of co-operation become larger and more and more complex and the desire of the Istituto di Credito for a regulation of credit grows proportion- atel}'. Hence the necessity that there shotUd always be at hand the ma- terial for learning the conditions of the enterprises as regards their economy and their capital in real estate. This gives a motive to all the co-operative societies to prove the value of their organizations, for it is from all of them together that operations of credit in general and of fiduciary credit in par- ticular can derive their indispensable effective guarantees ". The report cited shows the activity of these societies. In 1916 they kept the books of 54 co-operative societies and drew up their balance sheets : the office of Reggio did this for 31, that of Guastalla for 23. The inspecting office imdertook notable work. It revised 164 bal- ance-sheets, belonging, respectively, to 67 consumers' and 97 labourers' co-operative societies ; and it gave 195 consultations. The results obtained by revising the balance-sheets were the bases for the compilation of statistics of 1914, and the like are now being compil- ed for 1915. If the data collected be resumed the progress of co-opera- INFORMATION REI,ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 3 1 ticn in the region of Reggio in 1914 will be seen to present the following facts : Co-operative societies adhering to the Office of Inspection number 156 of which 74 are consumer's societies, 69 labour societies and 13 agricul- tural societies.' The total number of members is 20,580, distributed as follows : 9,204 in co-operative consumers' societies ; 8,876 in co-operative labourers' societies and 2,500 in co-operative agricultural societies. The subscribed capital amounts to 1,755,907 liras and reserves to 738,876 liras. The following figures represent the turnover : sales, 4,198,961 liras ; work 5,845,648 liras. The total amount of operations of credit effected by this institution of credit is as follows : From I Jul}^ 1911 to 31 December 1912 (18 months) 6,226,784.57 Hras In 1913 4.85'5,936.29 » » 1914 5,317,068.22 » . » 1915 6,134,063.15 )) » 1916 6,882,608.30 » Total . . . 29,417,460.53 » These data are proof of the importance of the work accomplished and also of the useful ser\dce rendered by this institution to co-operation. * 4. I,A FEDERAZIONE APISTICA ITAI^IANA. — UAgricoltura italiana, organ of the federation, Nos. i and 2, Ancona, January and Februarj', 1917. This Italian Apiarist Federation, which has its headquarters at Ancona, is a limited liabilit^^ co-operative society, having an unlimited capital and aiming at the production and sale of honey and wax (i). It was founded in 1904 on a modest scale but has developed constantly, as is shown by the following table. (i) The Federazione apistica subalpina is in course of construction at Turin in the form of a limited liability co-operative society aiming at a) the progress and popularization of rational apiculture ; b) the improvement of members' apiculture ; d) the collective purchase and use of everything necessary to the rational practice of this industry ; d) tlie marketing of products. See in this connection Apicoltore moderno, Nos. 3 and 4, Turin, March and April 191 7. 32 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Development of the Federation from 1904 to 1916. Year Society's capital Number of Turnover members Exporta- Total tion sales i Price by quintal, including packing 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 Liras 1.3 14 9,236 10,342 11,246 22,798 31,097 35.793 38,352 40,704 43,041 46,731 48,736 49,343 72 456 534 600 607 629 658 667 674 690 740 766 772 Iviras Quintals 1 Quintals I 2,087 . _ _ 419,226 175 : 757 1,392,060 385 1,606 1,640,864 625 1,453 1,995,906 605 2,032 3,237,223 707 1,889 2,608,849 1,598 2,714 3,021,493 1,168 1,495 2,058,948 i 582 1,207 3,555,330 ! 1. 137 2,577 4,694,611 1 1,420 3,741 — ! 958 2,414 - 1 - 2.135 Liras 76 68 77 76 71 74 100 98 84 72 The continuall}' increasing membership is explained by the advan- tages procured by this federation, and also by a very wise provision of the administrative council that members need pay immediately only half in- stead of the whole amount of a share of 50 liras, paying the rest in three annual instalments. 5. THE CONSTITUTION OF LA FEDERAZIONE DELLE LATTERIE SOCIAI^I CRE- MONESI. — Bollettino deU'Agricoltura, No. 7, Milan, 15 Februarj' 1917. Their common interests and the desirability of an interchange of ad- vice and assistance suggested to the collective dairies in the district of Cre- mona the idea of forming a federation, and to this the dairies of Soresina, Acquanegra, vSesto, Forcello, Ca de Stefani, Ca de Corti and Piadena have already adhered. The federation proposes to buy on behalf of the federated societies merchandise and products for common use and implements and machines ; to furnish information as to the most profit- able method of treating milk and the best markets ; to act in the markets as an intermediary ; to constitute depositing warehouses in order to faci- litate advances of funds ; and to organize the sale of products and produc- tion by specialization, by improvements and by encouraging the founda- tion of new co-operative societies. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCL^TION 33 RUSSIA. FINNISH CO-OPERATIVE DAIRIES IN 1915. — Suomen Osuustoimin talehti ; Helsing- fors, Year 1916, No. 10. At the end of 1915 there were 421 co-operative dairies in Finland, twenty-one of them having been founded during the year. These societies had 45,000 members, as against 41,500 in 1914 and 39,000 in 1913. Of the members 38.8 per cent, possessed from one to three cows, 53.9 per cent, from four to fifteen, and 7.3 per cent, more than fifteen. In 1913 the correspond- ing percentages were 38.4, 53.1 and 8.5 ; in 1911 they were 37.8,53.9 and 8.7. The following table shows the number of cows belonging to co-operative dairies and the proportion this bore to the country's total herd from 1912 to 1915 : In igi2 the co-operative societies possessed 250,000 cows or 21.6 % of the country's herd " 1913 " " " " 255,000 " " 21.7 % 1914 1915 269,000 288,000 22.7 % 25.7 % The increased percentage in 1915 was influenced by the notable reduc- tion in the country's total herd in that year. From the 421 co-operative dairies 316 million kilogrammes (i) of milk were obtained while in 191 4 the 396 co-operative dairies supplied 321 mil- lion kilogrammes. The chief cause of the diminished milk production in 1915 was doubtless the fixing of too low prices for butter which led to the slaughter of many milch-cows and thus paralysed all measures taken to increase milk production. As regards motive power, steam is employed by 266 dairies, h^-draulic power b}' eleven and electricity^ by seven, while fifty-four are content to use human labour and forty-eight have recourse to animal traction. The financial position of 330 co-operative dairies at the end of Decem- ber 1915 was as follows : Assets I^iabilities In hand Deposits and credit .... Real estate ... .... Frs. 739,919 4,173,229 6,131,944 .':4i,250 1,181,131 lyoans granted by the State . lyoans granted by the banks and other loans Capital owned by dairies. . . Excess of assets over liabilities Total . . . Frs. 1,144,279 2,405,775 6,7i3.f'65 2,303,754 Accessory industries .... Products and plant .... Total . . • 12,567.473 12,567,473 (i) I kilogramme = 2.2 lbs. 34 INFORMATION KEI.ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The financial position of the co-operative dairies is thus seen to have been excellent. The following table shows their financial dvelopment from 1904 to 1915 : Assets I,iabilities Real Estate Other property (in hand, deposits, etc.) Capital owned by dairies Ivoans 83.0% 17-0% 23-1 % 76.9 % 84.1 % 15.9% 26.8% 73.2 % 81.7% 18-3 % 34.0 % 66.0 % 77.7% 22.3 % 46.2 <% 53.8 % 67.7 % 32.3 % 60.5% 39.5 % 63.3 % 36.7 % 63.7 % 36.3 % 51.5% 48.5 % 71.8% 28.2 % 1904 1906 1908 I9IO I9I2 I9I4 I9I5 An examination of this table wiU convince the reader that the develop- ment of the co-operative dairies has been continuous and rapid. In 1904 they owned hardly a quarter of the capital they employed, but in 1912 they owned much more than half thereof, namely 60.5 per cent. And while their own capital increased the proportion of their real estate to their other property was modified to the advantage of the latter ; which in 1914 constituted 36.7 per cent, of all their assets, being thus equal to their debts (36.3 per cent.), whereas in 1915 the position had much improved. In 1915 the value of the products sold by the Finnish co-operative dai- ries was fifty million francs. The average income of a dairy was larger than it had ever been, namely 141,667 francs as against 110,727 francs in 1914 and 113,210 francs in 1913. But most of the dairies — 52.1 per cent, of them — have not yet attained to an annual turnover of 100,000 francs. There were at the end of 1915 nineteen large dairies having an annual turnover of more than 400,000 francs. The average price of the products was 379.53 francs for one hundred kilogrammes of butter in 1915, as against 281.05 francs in 1914. The cor- respondent cost of production reached 36.^13 francs and the net profit 343.10 francs. If 2 % per cent, be allowed for usurer's amortization a final net profit of 3.34 francs remains on one kilogramme of butter. To produce one kilogramme of butter 24.3 kilogrammes of milk are needed. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 35 UNITED STATES. THE ACTIVITY OF THE JEWISH AGRICUIvTURAI, AND INDUSTRIAI, AID SOCIETY IN 1916 (i). — From the society's annual report for 1916. The activity' of this society in 1916 was facilitated by the excellent economic situation of the United States and the high prices of agricultural products. Credit operations extended into thirty-six States ; 386 loans were made in the year for a total amount of $229,827, as against 396 in 1915 for a total amount of $190,036. Since the number of loans diminished while their total sum increased it follows that the average individual loan was larger : it rose from $480 in 1915 to $595 in 1916. This business brought the total number of loans made by the society since its foundation up to 4,100, and the total sum lent up to $ 2,330,091. At the close of 1916 loans which had not been repaid numbered 1,713 and amounted to $ 977,423. The following table shows the chief objects for which loans were made : Object of I' a substantial fence of not less than two strands of barbed wire upon posts not more than 33 feet apart, and are used ex- clusively for grazing and for growing hay, only b^' the person who wishes to withdrav/ them from insurance. 2) Unpatented quarter sections held under homestead, jjre-eniption or purchased homestead entrv', having less than 25 acres under cultivation. The ability to withdraw these allows new settlers and others who have only a small holding of cultivated land, exclusiveh^ on unpatented lands, to a\'oid paying the hail insurance tax until their lands are patented or until tliey come to be grain growers on a large scale. 3) A patented or unpatented quarter section in which less than 25 acres is under cultivation and the remaining land fenced as described un- der i). The provision for the withdrawal of land of this category is made in the interests of certain parts of the cotuitry where most of the land is graz- ing land and only a minor portion arable. d) Inspection oj Damage toy which Lndemnity is Claimed. -- This very important part of any scheme of insurance was inevitably found to admit of improvment after experience of it had been gained. In igiz] the Commission provided that an}' claimant who was dissat- isfied with the inspector's estimate of the damage his crop had incurred might ask to have it re-inspected. The system of re-inspection thus inaug- urated proved to be so useful that in 1915 the Commission further provid- ed that if after re-inspection the claimant were still dissatisfied, his claims could be referred to two arbitrators, one chosen by himself and the other by the chief or general inspector, and that these, after they had inspected the crop in question, had power to call in a third person who should de- MUNICIPAL INSURANCE AGAINST HAIL IN SASKATCHEWAN 41 cide points on wliich they could not agree. The Commission's regulations as to this provision are printed on the back of the report which the inspector leaves with the claimant after his first inspection. Onl}^ two claimants availed themselves of the provision in 1915, and in both cases the two arbi- trators agreed without calling in a third person and the award was not in- creased but reduced. Two general and twenty-one regular inspectors weie employed in 1915, all of them then or recently engaged in farming and eleven of them reeves or councillors of a municipality at the time of their appointment. e) Finance. — The following figures show the financial working of the scheme before 191 6. Number of Municipal- ities under the Act Number of Claims Received Amount paid in Claims Costs of Administration 1913 1914 I915 115 126 127 S 788,389.50 896,365.26 917.293 96 5,300 • 3.568 3,991 S 756,960.11 512,900.75 670,809.42 •S 26,928.52 30,029.24 35,871.51 These results were received as evidence of a great success by the Hail Insurance Commission. Nearly two million dollars had been paid to the farmers in indemnities ; in 1914 and 1915 payments, aggregating % 35,000, had been made into a tax adjustment reserve fund ; and a surplus of more than half a million dollars had been accumulated. In the report issued early in 1916 the Commissioners l^id stress on the economical nature of the scheme they administered. They stated that out of every dollar collected from the farmers 73 cents had been returned to them in the form of indemnities, 21 cents were held as a reser^^e fund against future abnormal losses, and only 6 cents were absorbed by the expenses of the Commission and the commission paid to secretaries of municipalities. In the case, however, of nineteen private insurance companies, which were the rivals of the Commission in the province, only ^j cents out of every dol- lar collected were returned to the farmers in the form of indemnities, and the remaining 67 cents went to pay expenses and make the profits of sharehold- ers. The insurance effected by the Commission would, if it had been car- ried on by private companies, have cost the farmers $ 3,000,000.00 more than had been the case. The Commission had originally no power to borrow money except for administrative purposes. It was however deemed advisable to in\est a portion of the surplus, and therefore the Act as amended in 1915 allowed the Commission to borrow money for any purpose, using its securities as colla- teral. f ) Additional Insurance. — There was some discontent with the amount of indemnities received for losse. was sit stated that when a crop was en- 42 CANADA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT tirely ruined by hail the indemnity of $ 5 an acre compensated not for the full value lost but onl}' for the cost of putting the crop in. To meet this com- plaint the Commission, as empowered by the amendments of 1915, inaugu- rated a system by which farmers in municipalities already under the Act might, by appl3dng to the secretary of their municipality, pay an addition- al rate of 5 cents an acre, and thus insure their crops for an additional § 5 an acre, or § 10 an acre in all. Participation in the additional insurance thus initiated was naturally confined to grain growers within the 139 municipahties under the Act, and even on their part it w^s entirely voluntary. There was therefore a danger that risks would not be sufficiently distributed. The Commissioners stated that to guard against this they had in the first place employed agents in all the municipalities under the Act to solicit adherence to the scheme for additional insurance ; and in the second place had arranged with several good insurance companies for reinsurance, in every district where risks which could not easily be faced were in the least likely to occur. The rate of 5 cents an acre was less by one cent than the usual rate, but the Commis- sioners claimed that this fact was justified by the economy of their adminis- tration. According to an approximate estimate pubhshed in vSeptember 1916 the value of the additional insurance in force was $ 2,000,000 and the total revenue from insurance $ 1,000,000. § 3. The BREAKDOWN OF THE SCHEME. a) The Results of 1906. In a review of the first three A^ears of their labours published at the end of 191 5 the Commissioners hint at a jjossible eventual abatement of the assessment rate of 4 cents an acre for insurance under the Act of 1912. "It is the intention of the Commission ", they say, ' to maintain the 4 cent assessment rate at least until the reserve fund equals one year's re\'enue, thus placing its finances upon a sound basis so that claims can be settled earlier in the season ". But far from bringing them nearer a point at which the}^ can lower the rate, 19 16 has proved the whole financial basis of this scheme for in- surance to be unsound. The following figures summarize the business of the year : Number of municipalities under the Act. . . 139 Approximate acreage under crop insured. . . 7,000,000 Number of Claims 10,000 Amount of Claims $3,600,000 I t. c.^ TA Z ( S3,DCO,000 Expenses $ 50,000 ) Revenue $ 950,000 Deficit on the year $2,700,000 MUNICIPAL INSURANCE AGAINST HAIL IN SASKATCHEWAN 43 In connection with this formidable deficit further remarks from the official re\dew issued late in 1915 may be cited. " The hail insurance levy of 5 cents per acre amounting to only $ 6.40 for 160 acres is a very small premiufn to carry a risk of $ 800, which is the case where all the acreage is under crop... In other words it takes 4 cents per acre levy upon 125 acres to pay... $ 5 upon one acre destroj-ei by hail ". It is instructive to compare with the results obtained by the Munici- pal Hail Insurance Commission those reached from 1913 to 1916 by pri- vate companies insuring against hail in Saskatchewan. In the aggregate they were as follows : Year Premiums Losses I9I3 $783,194.42 I9I4 747,838.68 I915 1,363,001.66 I916 1,417,853.21 1485.30579 I7344344 438,619.57 1.872,408.75 The following table shows the gross income and gross losses of each company insuring against hail in the province in 1916. Name of Company St. Paul Fire and Marine Insurance Company Middle West Excess Acadia Fire Canadian Indemnity Canada Hail " National Rochester Underwriters 'Agency British American Assurance Wiimipeg Fire Underwriters' Agency Nova Scotia" " Home Insurance Canada Security Assurance British Crown " Canada Weather Insurance American Cential " Connecticut Fire " Hartford New York Underwriters' Agencj- Great North Insurance Northwestern National Insurance Dominion Fire " Glens Falls " Westchester Fire " Losses 54,802.10 $ 86,251.54 39,662.35 49,690.94 102,437.75 130,739.14 31,860.86 66,593-02 82,582.10 124,728.45 72,542.95 95,127-67 95,685.18 193,055-43 20,909.56 29,243.26 48,176.13 64,539-13 3,150.96 3,887.50 9,657-87 11,686.87 102,646.13 176,608.61 70,898.97 83,93480 193,517.89 213,330.37 21,420.63 17,391-56 18,155-41 49,823.07 13,553-45 24,312.05 96,360.96 112,592.95 26,192.80 30,023.13 60,474.21 56,780.99 111,751.48 114,692.84 37,282.47 26,439.05 80,987.46 76,827.06 23,143-54 34,209.32 $ 1,417,853.21 $ 1,872,408.75 44 CANADA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT The expenses of the private companies in 1916 averaged 30 per cent of their premium inconK'. Since the losses were equivalent to about 132 per cent, of such income they owed, at the end of 1916, 162 per cent, of the total amount they had received in this year. The position was sufficiently serious, yet vastly less so than that of tlie Municipal Insurance Commission which, in spite of its much more economical administration, would have had to pay 394 per cent, of its premium income in order fully to indemnifj^ losses at the rate of $ 5 an acre. The private companies were able to meet all claims on them from their reserves. The Mimicipal Hail Insurance Commission was under no obli- gation to pay f uU compensation at the $ 5 an acre rate, for a clause, already cited, of the Act of 1912 provides that if the Commission consider that its revenues do not permit of full payment it shall meet claims pro rata. Only the 127 municipalities which were under the Act before 1916 had an}- claim to the reserves accumulated from surplus income before that year. It was calculated that the Commission was in a position to indemnify the farmers of these 127 municipalities for their losses at the rate of about S 2.15 an acre ; and those in the remaining thirteen municipalities, who had no claim on the reserves, at that of about .S 1.30 an acre. Indemni- fication at these rates could not go far to compensate for the actual loss, in view especially of the fact that the destruction of a large part of the crop would enormously raise the price of seed. b) Defects of the Scheme. i) As regards the causes of the breakdown the first defect in the mu- nicipal hail insurance scheme brought to light b}' the breakdown of 1916 was that it had been based on an inadequate estimate of risks. The rate of premium allowed for an average annual loss of 4 per cent, of the total crop. The loss in 1913 was 3 per cent., in 1914 it was i ^/^ per cent, in 1915 it was 2 per cent. : the average annual loss for these three years was therefore 2 V^ per cent. But in 1916 the loss was 10 per cent, and thus for the four years the annual average was 5 per cent, or i per cent, in excess of the estimate. Hence the failure of the scheme. It is stated that an absolute annual average should be calculated on a period of from fifty to sevent3"-five j^ears, and that no period of less than twenty-five years can give dependable data. 2) The scheme was therefore speculative. It was so in a second re- spect because while it competed with firms affording absolute insurance, the measure of insurace it actually gave was hypothetical, being limited by the pro rata clause. It is clear however that the commissioners advertised their benefits as equivalent or superior to those afforded by the private compa- nies, and that the insured farmers considered that their crops were unre- servedly insured against hail at the rate of $ 5 an acre. Further the pubHc character of the scheme seems to have given some of these farmers an idea that their compensation at tliis rate was guaranteed by the government. Thus a mass meeting held at Venn after the breakdown of the scheme MUNICIPAL INSURANCE AGAINST HAII, IN SASKATCHEWAN 45 resolved " that the provincial government be requested to loan the Commission enough money to pay all claims in full ". § 4. The PROPOSED AMENDEMNT OF THE SCHEME. A very general desire was shown by Saskatchewan farmers for the con- tinuance of the Municipal Hail Insurance Scheme in an amended form. It had been abundantly proved that insurance of this nature, since it was not profit-making but co-operative, and since it could be administered by the municipal organization, was less costly than the insurance af- forded by private firms if it could but be made equally secure. But under the existing scheme farmers could not have complete protection unless they insured with a private company the risk left uncovered by the Commission. Representatives of the rural municipalities under the Municipal Hail Insurance Act held a convention to consider the amendment of the scheme. At this meeting 39 municipaHties did not vote or were not represented, but 78 voted in favour, and only 22 against, the full payment of all the claims of 1916. Proposals for amending the scheme were submitted to the con- vention and all of thenr provided for a) such full payment, b) the rendering absolute of insurance as afforded by the scheme. Subsequently the convention appointed a committee consisting of the three Commissioners, the secretary of the Grain Growers' Association and five representative of the municipalities ; and these, at meetings held in Regina from 10 to 27 November 1916, considered the proposals submit- ted to the convention and other suggestions for amending the scheme. Their report was presented to the reeves and representatives of rural municipa- lities under the Act and to the provincial government on 27 November. a) Provision for Meeting Losses of 1916 in Full. The committee offered two alternative suggestions for the meeting of the losses of 1 916 in full. i) They proposed that the ratepayers should be consulted as to whe- ther they would agree to a special levy of 2 cents an acre during 1917 only, the amount accruing from such levy to be applied in part payment of the losses of 1 91 6. 2) They pro])Osed that the rural municipalities under the Act should have an opportunity of voting as to whether they would accept resj^onsi- bility for the 1916 deficit, on condition that if not less than eighty of them agreed to meet their proportion of such deficit, such eighty would be re- quired to make provision, by sinking fund, debenture issue or otherwise or through the commission, to meet for ten years an annual call for not more than $3,000 from each municipality. 46 CANADA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT b) Provision for Making Insurance Absolute. i) Suggested Plans. — The committee pointed out in their report that insurance could be made absolute by three methods : by the possession of a surplus of other assets equal to the insurance at risk ; by a mutual company in which each of the insured would agree to pay the levies in full in any 3^ear ; or by an unknown compulsory tax upon the land. The first of these expedients was out of the question because the 1916 losses would leave over neither surplus nor current revenue, and the as- sets pro\4ding for the future were Umited. The second method was only appHcable to a scheme under which individuals voluntarily applied for insurance. The third method if appHed in its simplest form would involve the levying on all assessable lands, at the end of an^^ year in wliich revenue had been inadequate to paying indemnities at the agreed rate, of a tax suf- ficient to cover the deficit. Such additional assessment would in 1916 have been 16 cents, an acre if this method of indemnifying at the rate of $5 an acre had been adopted. The full cost of insurance in that year would therefore have been 20 cents an acre. The committee did not deem it wise or just to burden the land with liability to such a tax. Even so important a matter as insurance against hail did not, in their opinion, justify this placing on the land, which already contributed largely to public objects, of a bvurden which could not be estimat- ed beforehand and might be very onerous. Under the existing system holders of land in municipalities under the Act are in the position of members of a limited mutual company in which the majority, who are grain growers, compel not only themselves but also the minority, who are not grain growers, to pay a fixed charge upon their lands in order to protect only the grain growers. Proposals were therefore made which sought to limit liabilit}^ to an additional tax to grain growers. The details of one of these plans may be given. It aimed at ensur- ing that those actually enjoying protection should have full mutual respon- sibility for the insurance ; and that a sufficient accumulated surplus should be procured to give ample protection in case of a year or years of extraor- dinary loss. It proposed therefore that neither the 4 cent per acre assess- ment rate nor the $ 5 maximum indemnity should be altered ; but that an extra and variable rate beginning at 12 cents an acre should be levied on all crops at risk, which rate should be lowered only when a surplus equal to 10 per cent, of the risk carried had been accumulated. Any farmer was to be allowed to withdraw his crop acreage from this assessment b}' foregoing aU claim upon the protection of the Commission. No municipality was to be permitted to withdraw from the scheme while it was indebted to the Commission, or in any circumstances without two 5'ears' notice. The Com- mission was to have power to levy on the insured crop acreage an emergency rate, not exceeding 20 cents an acre in any one year, with which to meet MUNICIPAL INSURANCE AGAINST HAIL IN SASKATCHEWAN 47 any deficit which might occur. Should this be insufficient a pro rata distri- bution of available funds was to be made among claimants, and any re- maining deficit paid out of the possible surplus in the succeeding year, or if this should fail by means of the levy of another and similar 20 cent rate. This and kindred plans were however rejected by the committee on the grounds of impracticability. " A great deal has been said and written" , thej^ state in their report, " about making an assessment upon the assessed acreage or upon the ' excess seeded acreage '. We have fully discusssed the advisabiHty of making an assessment of this kind and our opinion is that such assessment would not be practicable at the present time. In the course of a few years it might be possible to provide the administra- tive municipal machinery necessary to secure the accurate information upon which such an assessment must be based, and which would have to be se- cured yearly prior to 15 June from each individual ratepayer. To make such an assessment in 1917 would be practically impossible without a heavy expense being incurred in each municipaUty. The ' excess seeded acreage ' assessment is a more or less compHcated form of assessment upon the seeded acreage basis ". 2. Plan adopted by the Committee. — The proposal of the committee was that " the revenue of the commission be raised by a flat rate of 6 cents per acre upon all assessable lands in the municipalities except such as are withdrawn and that the pro rata clause be retained ". The adoption of the committee's proposal by the legislature will there- fore leave the insurance still hypothetical, in theory if not in practice. The committee in substance declined the responsibility of making a proposal for guaranteed absolute protection. " There is no doubt ", runs their report, ' ' that reUable data to place hail insurance rates upon cannot be secured ; hail insurance has not been in general operation long enough to provide such information, we can only use such figures as are available and when we recommend an increase of 50 per cent, over the existing rate, and when we consider that if stich a rate had been in operation from the inception of the scheme all the losses including 1916 could have been paid in full, we beheve that we are recommending a rate that will not be oppressive, that will not depart from the present method of assessment, that will give full protection in ordinary years and a fair protection in disastrous years, a rate that the ratepa3-er will know is the maximum amount that can be charged upon him, and a rate that will place the present system upon a safer and sounder financial basis than it has been on heretofore ". The committee further proposed that the Commission should be dis- abled from reducing the fixed rate of premiums " until a surplus has been accumulated which together with the current rate would equal 12 per cent, of the risk carried ". c) Further Amendments Proposed. As regards lands which may annually be withdrawn from insurance, the committee proposed that the second and third categories of these should include patented or unpatented quarter sections, as already described, 48 CANADA - INSURANCE AND THRIFT in which less than 40 acres were under cultivation, instead of 25 acres as at present. They proposed also to add to these categories two others — namely holdings of not more than 640 acres of land of any owner or occu- pant, of which one fourth or more were under cultivation ; and holdings of like extent of which one half or more were under cultivation — and proposed further that land in these two additional categories might be withdrawn for three years. They proposed to render it necessary to give notice of damage incurred by a crop to the secretary of the Commission within three days of the fall of hail, instead of within five days as at present. They proposed that the Act should be administered b}" a board of nine directors who should be elected by the annual meeting of the reeves of the municipalities under the Act, nine to be elected by the first meeting and thereafter three each year. Finally they proposed that the government should be asked to provide that all rural municipahties which did not submit a repeaUng b^^-law, upon a petition signed by fifty resident ratepayers, and did not approve such by- law before a date in 1917 yet to be fixed, should automatically remain under the amended Act. In presenting their report to the municipalities the committee stated that they intended to meet again before the amending legislation was enacted, and expressed themselves ready to receive suggestions made after the report had been considered in the municipal councils or the annual ratepayers' meetings. Part III: Credit RUMANIA. AGRICUIvTURAL CREDIT IN RUMANIA. OFPICIAI, SOURCE : Anurul statistic al Romaniei {Statistical Yearbook of Rumania). — Bucharest, i- as to the agricultural class ; for in this country more than elsewhere there has been a division of labour among the different institutions giving agricultural credit, and this division is based on the differences between the agricultural classes. Until 1862 the feudal system obtained in Rumania. All the land belong- ed to a limited class of feudatories, who were called boyards and numbered bout 5000, and it was cultivated by 470,000 families belonging to the class of land serfs. The class of small proprietors was represented only by the 100,000 families of the Mosneni in Vallachia and the Rasesi in Moldavia. Side by side with individual feudatories the State and the churches and monasteries held vast territories. In 1862 the feudal system was abolished. The law of 15 August 1864 ordered that part of the ]jroperty of the feudatories should be distributed among the cultivators. Later in 1866, 1869, 1876, 1881 and 1889 the dis- tribution of the lands belonging to the State and the churches was ordered ; and in 1908 a rural bank was formed with the object of granting credit to the fanners in order that they might buy land 50 RUMANIA - CREDIT Nevertheless the distribution of landed property in Rumania is far from satisfactory, as is seen from the following table : 62,832 farmers have less than %- hectare (i) that is 26,426 hectares or 0.34 % 81,039 " 14-1 147,900 " " " 1-2 131,630 " 2-3 172,446 3-4 148,717 4-5 744,564 5 176,375 5-10 36,318 " " 10-50 2,405 " " 50-100 38,723 " " 10-100 4,171 " more than 100 72,757 " " 0.93 % 237,029 3-01 % 337,000 4-30 % 631,964 " 8.08 % 711,033 " " 9-o8 % 2,016,209 " '•' 25.74 % 1,137,136 " " 14-55 % 695,953 " " 2.13 % 166,847 " 8.89 % 862,800 " 11.02 % 3,810,351 " 48.69 % Side by side with this class of farmer-proprietors there is one of landless agriculturists which comprises from 250,000 to 300,000 families. The table we have given shows that there are two classes of landed pro- prietors in Rumania : i) Farmers owning a small property of less than 10 hectares. This class is represented by about 920,939 families who own altogether 3,153.675 hectares or 40.29 per cent, of the cultivated land. 2) The class of large proprietors, owning more than 100 hectares, is represented by 4,171 families owning altogether 3,810,351 hectares or 48.69 per cent, of the cultivated land. Besides these classes there are that of the landless agriculturists, repre- sented by from 250,000 to 300,000 families ; and that of owners of medium- sized properties, of from ten to a hundred hectares, which is represented by only 38,723 families who own 862,800 hectares or 11 per cent, of the cultivated land. The work attached to credit transactions with large and with small proprietors has been divided among the various institutions of agricultural credit. Those dealing with the large proprietors are : i) Creiliiul fonder rural, 2) Banca aqricola. Those dealing with the small proprietors are : 3) Crditul af.ricol si viticol, 4) Banctle popidare, 5) Casa rurala. We will deal with these institutions later. (1) I hectare = 2.47 acres. , AGRlCUIvTURAI, CREDIT 5 1 ' § 2. Rural I^anu Credit (Creditul foncikr rural). The first credit institution in Rumania to do business in mortgage credit was the Moldavian Bank formed in 1856. This was a stock company, form- ed with foreign capital, which in addition to its other banking business granted short or long-term mortgage credit to large proprietors. The long term mortgages were redeemable in seventeen years, the mortgagers being obliged to pay ten per cent, as interest and amortization quota. Towards i860 this bank ceased to deal in credit and from that date its only transaction within that sphere has been the liquidation of business then in course. In 1872 the government brought before the chamber a scheme for the formation of a mortgage bank. According to this scheme the bank would have been a stock company and would have enjoyed the monopoly of grant- ing mortgage credit and issuing mortgage titles on the basis of the credit granted. It would bave been authorized to grant to landowners not onl}^ mort- gage credit but also short-term credit for working funds, and to make ad- vances to the State and the communes. The scheme encountered in the chamber the lively opposition of the large proprietors who criticized it vehemently under the three follow- ing heads ; i) They proposed that instead of a stock-company there should be a co-operative society of large proprietors based on the principle of collective liability. 2) They proposed that there should not be a single institution enjoy- ing a monopoly of the business of mortgage credits and the issue of mortgage titles, but that the law shoxdd prescribe the conditions on which such business should norniallj' be done, so that every society of landowners would have to fulfil these conditions before it would be authorized to grant credit or issue mortgage titles. 3) Finally they proposed that the task of granting mortgage credit on rural and on urban lands should be di^'ided among the institutions. These proposals were all passed by a majority in the chamber and were reproduced in the law of 5-17 April 1873. Under this laW sixty large proprietors having property worth at least three million francs (i) were authorized to form a mortgage bank., if they would accept the clause imposing collective liability. The bank was to have the form of a co-operative society which could have no members other than landowners. The entrance of these into the society was to be o]:)tional: but all landowners receiving credit were to be considered as members ipso facto and to be collectively responsible for all the bank's engagements to the extent of the value of their mortgaged lands. The law prescribes the division of functions to obtain between banks granting mortgage credit on (i) I franc = 9 '/g ^ at par. 52 RUMANIA - CREDIT cultivated land and those granting it to proprietors of urban land. It makes the maximum rate of interest 7 per cent. On the basis of this law there have hitherto been founded: a mortgage bank for granting credit to proprietors of rural lands, and two mortgage banks — at Bucharest and J assy — for granting it to owners of urban land. We will here deal only with the first of these banks which was founded 1-13 June 1873 at Bucharest and is called the Prima Societate de Creditul Fun- ciar Ruman (First Society of Rumanian Ivand Credit). The following are the chief characteristics of this bank : i) It has no capital in shares, that is its members pay no admis- sion fee. A due of 2 per cent, is however levied on the credit granted, and thus is formed a guarantee fund which remains in the bank until the debt is extinguished. When it has been extinguished the mortgager receives the whole deducted sum without interest. Side by side with this guarantee fund there is a reserve fund, formed of : a) ^ per cent, on all credit granted ; b) 90 per cent, of net profits. The reserve fund is the bank's property and is restored to the mortgagers only after the extinction of debts. The deduction of 14 ^^^ 90 P^'^ cent, is interrupted as soon as the reserve fund amounts to 5 per cent, of the amount of existing debts. 2) The bank grants credit onl}^ to owners of rural land. The grants are for long and short terms. lyong-term credit (ten to sixty years) is secured by a first mortgage of rural lands and may not be for more than 50 per cent, of the value of the mortgaged land. The debt is extinguished by annual amortization. Short-term credit (three to ten years) is also guaranteed by a first mortgage on rural lands : the debt is extinguished by annual amortiza- tion or it is repaid in a single sum. Mortgagers used in the bank's first years to pay interest at the rate of 7 per cent, but this rate is now 5 per cent 3) The mortgager receives the amount of his advance in mortgage titles at par. He must himself place them on the market for securities. When he pays the amortization quota of his debt he may do so in cash or in mortgage titles at par. The mortgage titles are payable to bearer in sixl}^ years, and all State banks accept them as security. Until 1881 they produced interest at the rate of 7 per cent. The rate was in that year reduced to 5 per cent, and titles previously issued were then convertd. Since 1898 only mortgage titles at 4 per cent, have been issued. Those at 5 per cent, have not however been converted so that both are in circulation. 4) Until 1882 the bank was authorized to grant credit seciired by mortgage titles, but business of this nature has since been forbidden and suspended. 5) The adininistrative council has eight members elected by the ge- neral meeting. Side by side with it there are the managers, namely one manager and two vice-managers, all nominated by the administrative coiin- cil. The right of inspection belongs to a government commissioner nomi- nated by the Minister of Finances. 6) A deduction ofjjgo per cent, is made from net profits in order to AGRICULTURAI, CREDIT 53 form a reserve fund ; the remaining 10 per cent, is divided among the mem- bers in proportion to their amortization. payments. The business of 1914 gave the following data : Guarantee fund 10,600,900 francs Reser\^e " 30,409,826 Credit granted 467,613,834 Mortgage titles in circulation . . . 467,585,964 namely ! ^^ 5 per cent . . . 327,385,112.50 } " 4 " " ... 140,200,851.50 Altogether 2,000 properties were mortgaged. § 3. The Agriculturai. Bank (Banca Agricdla). Besides the Credikd fonder rural, which gives land credit to large proprie- tors, there is the bank called the Banca Agricola wliich provides them with working capital. It was founded in 1894 on the basis of the law passed on 28 March of that year. It is legally a stock company. During the parlia- mentary debate on the law cited, in 1893-1894, the large proprietors proposed the formation of a societ}' based on the principle of the collective liability of all its members, but this proposal was not accepted and the bank re- tained the form of a stock compan}', in accordance with the government's scheme. The bank has its headquarterst at Bucharest ; and has five branches — at Braila, Jassy, Constanza, Craiova and Galatz — , and twelve agencies, — at Botosani, Buzen, Calafat, Calara.si, Palticeni, Guirgni, Roman, Fecuci Fulcea, Vaseni, Ramnicu-Sarat and Turnu-Magurele. Its capital in shares is 7,938,125 francs, di\dded into 24,425 shares of 325 francs each. A capital in shares of 12,212,500 francs was at first antici- pated, that is 24,425 shares of 500 francs each. Before however it was com- pletely paid up a reduction of 175 francs a share was made. This capital in shares can, if need be, be brought up to twenty million francs. The Banca Agricola receives, in addition to its own capital, outside capital : a) credit granted by the national bank ; h) deposits of individuals. It may also issue bonds (Kaesabons) secured by the credit it lias granted. These bear the number of the credit operation on the security of which they have been issued, and may be in circulation for a month or more. The total sum of bonds in circulation must not exceed 50 per cent, of the paid-up capital. The business of the Banca Agricola is as follows : i) It grants credit secured by pledged property- — cereals, live stock and agricultural implements — and on warrants. The cereals may be pledged before the harvest. The credit granted may not exceed 50 per cent, of the value of the pledges, or — if granted before the harvest — 30 per cent. All pledges must be insured. 54 RUMANIA - CREDIT 2) It Opens current accounts on the security of values. 3) It discounts and rediscounts bills. Transactions of these three descriptions are for short terras, the loans falling due in from three to nine months. The rate of interest varies with that of the National Bank but may not surpass 3 per cent. Further the Banca Agricola undertakes the following business: it receives payments on behalf on its clients ; it buys and sells provisions on commission ; on behalf of its clients it undertakes all the business connected with the storage of merchandise etc. B}^ the law of 1906 it is authorized to found general storehouses and to store merchandise, but it has not yet begun business of this sort. The management of the bank in 1911 furnished the following figures : Capital in shares fr. 7,938,125.00 Reserve fund " 3,366,630.54 Deposits " 20,684,405.05 Debts on rediscounted bills ... " 10,036,976.96 Current liability accounts at the Na- tional Bank " 11,405,932 Various current liability accounts . " 8,152,623 Advances on cereals ...... " 8,082,166.33 values " 10,781,032.10 Ciirrent credit accounts " 18,658,695.43 Credit in bills " 16,016,601.41 Various assets " 7,787,542.75 § 4. The Credit Institutions favouring small Properties. The " Casa Rurai.e ". This rural bank was formed in 1908. The special law passed on 4 April 1908 aimed at providing credit for landless agriculturists or those having only a very small property, thus enabling them, to buy land or increase their property. The tendency of the law is thus to create small proprietors. The formation of small properties was from 1862 part of the economic programme of the Rumanian government. In that year the feudal system was abolished. Soon afterwards, in 1864, the law was passed as to the compulsory sale of part of the propert}^ of large proprietors. In subsequent years — 1866, 1869, 1876, 1881 and 1889 — the laws were passed as to the distribu- tion of the lands of domains and churches among landless farmers or those owning only a verj' small property. The distribution of landed pro- perty is however still far from being reasonable. The exceSvSive increase of the agricultural population on the one hand and the laws on succession on the other have attenuated the effects of the laws we have enumerated, so that the commission of enquiry nominated after the peasants' revolt of 1907 could state in its report : i) that from 250,000 to 300,000 agricultural families had no property; AGRlCUIvTURAI, CREDIT 55 2) that 423,401 agricultural families, or 46 per cent, of their whole number, owned less than three hectares, which in view of the fact that ex- tensive agriculture prevails may be taken to be insufficent for the mainte- nance of a family. Thus from 673,000 to 723,000 families are constrained to seek work on the estates of the large proprietors. The first scheme for the formation of a rural bank dates from 1897. The Minister of the Pubhc Domain, P. S. Aurelian, presented to the chamber a scheme for the formation of a rural bank as a credit institution of the State. But the change in the ministry which took place soon afterwards delayed this scheme. In igo6 the qiiestion was again inserted in the agenda. A commission, to which D. Strudza, J. Bratianu nd G. D. Creanga belonged, was then nomi- nated and charged to recast Aurelian's scheme. The commission drew up an entirely new scheme which it presented to the chamber in igo8 ; and hav- ing been voted by ParUament and received the royal sanction the law en- tered into force on 4 April 1908. The Rural Bank has its offices at Bucharest. Legally it is a stock com- pany. Its capital in shares is of ten million francs divided into 20,000 shares of 500 francs each. Half the shares were subscribed by the State which at once paid up 60 per cent ; the other half were subscribed by individual capi- talists who must pay up at least 10 per cent, of their subscription. The shares are nominative and can be bought only by Rumanians. The capital in shares may be brought up to the sum of 20,000,000 francs on condition half the shares are acquired by the State. Besides its capital in .shares the bank obtains credit from the National Bank and capitalists by its issue of rural bonds. The following business is undertaken b}^ the bank : i) The purchase of domanial landed property and private property in order to divide it into parcels and sell it to landless agriculturists or small pro- prietors, and exceptionally to the communes or the State. Where the pur- chase of State lands is concerned no legal provision limits the action of the Rural Bank. In the case of private property the law forbids the purcha.se of estates of less than 200 hectares. It is clearly the aim of the law to pre- serve medium-sized properties. The Rural Bank pays the price of the land to the sellers either in cash or in bonds. These bonds bear interest at the rate of 5 per cent, and are amortizable in fifty years. They are issued on the security of the mortgage credit afforded by the bank to agriculturists or the land bought by the rural bank. The total value of the bonds in circulation nmst not surpass the sum of the mortgage credit granted, plus 80 per cent, of the value of the lands which the bank has bought and which are provisionally in its posses- sion. 2) The lands bought by the bank are sold to agriculturists and excep- tionally to the communes and the State. Before the sale those on the ])lain are divided into five-hectare and those in the mountains into three-hectare parcels. Exceptionally and when there are no purchasers for such lots 56 RUMANIA - CREDIT they may be divided into larger lots having a maximum area of fifty hec- tares. In accordance with the size of the purchasing family, and the cir- cumstance that the agriculturist purchaser is or is not already in possession of a small landed property, the number of lots which he may buy is deter- mined, the maximum being five. The price of each lot is calculated on the basis that it may not exceed by more than lo per cent, that paid by the bank. Purchasers are bound to pay in cash a part of the price, namely : 10 to 15 per cent, thereof if they buy i parcel, 25 " " " " " " 2 or 3 parcels 30 " " " " " " ^ to 5 The remainder of the price is debited to the purchaser by the Rural Bank and secured by a mortgage on the parcels bought. These debts are for long terms, amortizable in 50 years and paying interest at the rate of 5 per cent., plus 2 per cent, for unpunctual debtors. Purchasers of the parcels become owners thereof but do not enjoy them quite freely. Certain restrictions are imposed by the contract of purchase and sale, for example : a) the proprietor may rot resell his property nor let it on lease ; h) division by inheritance may take place only if the area of the pro- perty surpass five hectares, and may in this case only afi'ect the area in excess of five hectares ; c) the Rural Bank may inspect the farming of the parcels and does so by means of agricultural experts. If the land intended to be sold in parcels is six kilometres (i) or more distant from a village, a new village is formed ; and then before the division takes place land is set aside as the site of private dwellings and also of the church, the school, the mayoralty, etc. We have already said that the Rural Bank may sell land exceptionally to the communes and the State. To the communes the land needed to form communal pastures is sold ; to the State woodland. In the interval between the purchase of lands and their sale to small farmers the Rural Banks may grant them on lease or cultivate them directly. Beases are given by preference to co-operative letting societies. The bank's direct cultivation and the leases it grants are considered provisional and have force only pending the division into parcels or the execution of works of improvement, the ultimate object of the bank's purchase of lands being always to resell them in parcels. 3) The Rural Bank also intervenes between large and small proprie- tors in negotiations for the purchase and sale of lands. It is even authoriz- ed by law to fix the price of land, either by whole properties or by hectare. This right is incontestably a serious restriction of individual liberty ; but it is considered necessary because the agriculturist is alwa^^s very anxious to acquire land and therefore might easily consent to pay an exorbitant price for it. (i) I Kilometre = 1093.633 yards. agricuIvTtjRai, credit 57 4) The Rural Bank grants mortgage credit to agriculturists : a) for the purchase of parcels from itself ; b) for the direct purchase of land from large proprietors ; c) for the conversion of debts incurred by such pur- chase of lands before the foundation of the. bank. Credit for these purposes is secured by mortgages of the land in question. The mortgage is for a long term and the interest is at the rate of 3 per cent. The creditors of the debts mentioned under c) maj' be paid by the bank either in cash or in bonds, as they please. As well as the long-term credit, granted as stated, the Rural Bank grants to agriculturists short-term credit, secured by bills or pledged agricultural products, agricultural machines, live stock and values. 5) The Rural Bank is authorized by the law to carr}^ on every kind of banking business: the discount of commercial bills, the purchase and sale of titles, etc. This legal provision is justifiably criticized for it makes possi- ble the diminution of the bank's capital to the detriment of the business cited under numbers i) to 4). In practice however the Rural Bank does little of this banking business. Net profits are di\ided as follows : 70 per cent, to shareholders and 30 per cent, to the reserve fund. The State takes, in its capacity of share- holder, only 6 per cent, on the capital it has paid up, all the balance being assigned to the improvements fund. The conduct of the Rural Bank has provided the following figures : From the time it was founded until 31 Decembre 1913 it bought the following properties : Year Hectares Value 190S 8,308 4,200,940 francs 1909 18,736 9,532,828 191^ 30,597 16.392,155 191 1 18,459 13,256,991 I9I2 12,893 12,342,146 I9I3 26,473 20,068,824 115,467 15,793,886 Of these 115,467 hectares only 20,171 are wooded and therefore capable of being sold to the vState. The Rural Bank has sold a) to the communes ^,709 hectares for 28,909,600 francs ; and h) to agriculturists as follows : Number Year of parcels Hectares Francs 1909 124 519 43^'.43o 1910 458 2,183 1,778,288 1911 856 3,751 2,696,774 1912 1,324 5,971 4,695,285 1913 870 3,943 3,537.845 3,632 16,369 13,144,621 58 RUMANIA - CREDIT These 3,632 parcels '.vere sold to 3,318 agriculturists, which is to say that 89 per cerxt. bought only one parcel each. In addition to its sales the bank has let on lease: 20,856 hectares to fourteen collective farms comprising 3,677 members ; and 17,777 hectares to 5,099 agriculturists. The remainder — namely 32,187 hectares of arable land and 20,171 hec- tares of woodland — is directly cultivated and its profits realized Ijy the bank. The Rural Bank has granted 4,128,912 francs on mortgages to agricul- turists who have bought their lands directly from large proprietors. At the end of 1913 the shoit-term credit granted amounted to 5,602,048.65 francs. The value of the credit granted to communes was 28,647,200 francs. Net profits in 1913 were 990,450.69 francs. This sum was distributed as follows : To the reserve fund 30 per cent. 297,135.00 francs To the .shareholders 30 » » 646,657.80 » To the improvement funds . . 30 » » 46,657.89 » According to the balance-sheet of 1913 the reserve fund was 1,179,754 francs. § 5. Agricui^tural and Viticulturai, Credit (Creditul Agricol si VlilCOI.). On 30 Ma}^ 1881 the law as to departmental agricultural banks was passed in Rumania. The first of these banks was founded in 1882 and gradually there came to be one of them in each department. lyCgally they are stock-companies. In the intention of the law aU shares were to be subscribed by the agriculturists of the departments, but this was reahzed only in the agricultural bank of Jassy. The subscription of shares in all other departments was very small and the State was obhged to provide the necessary working capital in the form of loans to the banks. In 1892, the year in which the working of the banks was arrested, the loans granted by the vState amounted to seven milhon francs. The activity of each bank was limited to the department in which it was situated. The banks were completely independent of each other. They were authorized to grant to agriculturists only short-term credit, for terms of nine months, the security being : a) hills ; b) pledged agricultural products or macliines and values. The rate of interest was at first 7 per cent, but was raised to 11 per cent., and if dues to be paid on documentary evidence supplied or drawn up be included the actual rate was often from 15 to 20 per cent. The law prescribed no maximum for loans to agriculturists. Thus at the beginning of each year all or almost all the available capital was engrossed b)^ a restricted number of medium-sized proprietors, and small proprietors derived no benefit from the banks. Their unsatisfactory results decided / AGRICULTURAL CREDIT 59 the government to decree their suspension by the law of 2 July 1892, and to supersede them, by the Agricultural Credit which began business on i Jan- uary 1913. Instead of the decentralization which had hitherto prevailed a cen- tralization of business was brought about by the law of 1S92. An agricul- tural bank was formed which was situated at Bucharest and had branches in all the departmental centres in which there had previously been an agri- cultural departmental bank. Tliis institution of agricultural credit is a State institution depenchng on the Minister of Finances (art. 9). It has three sections : a) Section I. is concerned with mortgage credit. b) Section II. is concerned with long-term debts of a particular kind, debts namely incurred for initial installation under the law of 1889. c;) Section III., formed in 1906, grants long-term credit for the plan- tation of vineyards. The capital in shares paid by the State is 25,000,000 francs, namely : 20,000,000 francs to the first, 3,000,000 francs to the second and 2,000,000 francs to the third section. The capital was paid as follows : i) The first section received the sums granted by the State in the form of a loan to the departmental banks, namely 7,000,000 francs, and i': received 13,000,000 francs in State bonds (art. 12). * 2) The second section was granted a current account at the National Bank and the »State issued bonds up to the value of the credit granted. 3) The third section received for four years 500,000 francs a year — namely a total sum of 2,000,000 francs -— deducted from the net profits of the first section . Besides the capital in shares belonging to the State the Agricidtural Credit uses capital emanating from other sources. The first section is authorized : u) to accept deposits ; I) to borrow from the National Bank proportiotiately to the credit granted to its clients. The third section is also authorized to issue bonds secured by the credit granted. These bonds of 100-200 francs and 500 trancs are at 4 ^/2 per cent, redeemable in twenty years, and the total value of those issued must not surpass 20,000,000 francs. Section I. grants short-term credit, for from three to nine months, secured b}'' pledged agricultural products and machines and live stock. The rate of interest is 11 per cent, for costs of administration, plus 2 per cent, for unpunctual debtors. The total credit granted to a borrower must not be more than 1000 francs. Section I. is, as has already been said, authoriz- ed to accept deposits and also to receive payments on behalf of the Na- tional and the Agricultural Bank. From 1903 to 1906 Section I. had the responsibility of acting as a central bank for the agricultural co-operativ^e credit societies ; and as such was authorized to discount and rediscount the societies' bills and make loans to them on current account. In 1906 a truely independent central bank for the co-operative societies was formed, and thus the Agricultural Credit no longer undertook business of this description. 60 RUMANIA. - CREDIT Of the net profits 90 per cent, belong to the State and 10 per cent, are deducted to he paid into the reser\^e fund. The deductions for the reserve fund will cease as soon as its amount has reached 5,000,000 francs. Section II. grants both long and short-term credit for from three to ten years. This credit is granted for initial installation. According to the law of 1889 (art. 3) the Ministry of the Public Domains is authorized to sell the State's landed property in 5-hectare lots. The purchasers of these lots are obliged to establish themselves on them within three years. Sec- tion II. facilitates settlement of this description by granting to the settlers loans enabling them to build dwellings and buy live stock and agricultural implements. No more than 600 francs may thus be lent to a single bor- rower. The rate of interest is 5 per cent. Section III. was formed on 16 Januarj^ 1906. On 27 May of that year it was separated from the Agricultural Credit and remained separate until 30 INIarch 1908 when it once more became Section III. thereof. It makes long-term loans, for twenty years, for the plantation of vines. All its loans are guaranteed by the State on the security of a mortgage on the planted vines. The sum of the loan may not exceed two thirds of the value of the vineyard. The credit granted is supplied to the borrower on account as gradually the planting, which is inspected by an emplo3'ee of the lending institution, is effected. The rate of interest is 5 % per cent., plus i per cent, for impunctual borrowers (art. 7). The loans are amortizable in fifteen years but the first repayment does not take place until after five years, at which date the vines are beginning to be productive. From 1882 to 1892 the departmental banks granted creditfor 188,194,892 francs. When they ceased to work in 1892 the total credit they had grant- ed was for 19,988,041.35 francs, and this credit was transferred to the Agri- cultural Credit. From 1903 to 31 December 1911 Section I. of the Agricultural Credit granted credit for 504,594,240 francs. At the end of 1911 the amount of the credit was 16,984,046.05 francs. At the same time the following deposits were received : From 1882 to 1892 5.133.534 francs " 1893 " 1911 33,111,507.26 On I January 1912 deposits amounted to 3,374,123.84 francs. On 31 December 1911 the reser^^e fmid amounted to 2,608,693. 12 francs. From 1893 to 31 December 1911 the net profits paid to the State amoun- ted to 27,478,238.08 francs, that is a sum 4,478,238.08 francs in excess of the amount of the capital advanced by the State. Section II. in only four yearS (1894, 1895, 1897 and 1898) granted cre- dit to the amount of 862,060 francs. Section III. began business in 1907 and granted credit for the following sums : 943,100 francs in 1907 ; 1,297,600 francs in 1908 ; 1,045,600 francs in 1909; 846,800 francs in 1910 ; 3,271,000 francs from 1911 to 1914 — that is a total sum of 7,404,100 francs from 1907 to 1914. AGRICULTURAL CREDIT 6 1 One fifth of this credit was granted in the district of Prahova and large sums in the districts of Buzan, Doej and Valcea. The other districts par- ticipated only to a small extent. Bonds in circulation amounted on 31 March 1915 to 5,404,100 francs. The repayment of loans begins, as we have said, only after five years ; that is to say payments were made in 1912 for loans of 1907, in 1913 for loans of 1907 and 190S, and in 1914 for loans of 1907,1908 and 1909. This delay of five years before first repayments are made brings about that books are closed showing a loss which is only apparent. For the year 1915 it was 767,346.49 francs. § 6. The Rural Co-operative Credit Societies. The first rural co-operative credit society was formed at Urziceni in the department of Jalomiza in Januar>^ 1891. In subsequent years until 1898 the co-operative movement did not make much progress. Agriculturists had no confidence in the societies. The large farmers and the usurers were opposed to them seeing in them formidable competitors. The State was completely indifferent. For all these reasons the co-operative movement was slow in these first years. Only twenty-five rural co-operative credit societies were founded from 1891 to 1898. In 1898 Spira Haret was nominated Minister of Religion and he devoted himself to the development of the co-operative movement. He charged some masters of primary schools to teach the peasants the usefulness of co-opera- tive societies and the need there was for them. From this year the co-opera- tive movement developed, and when the law on co-operative societies was passed in 1903 there were already more than 700 of them. All were of the Schultze-Dehtsch type — that is to say they were limited liability societies. The law of 1903 caused the co-operative movement to enter into a new phase. The proposed law as presented to parhament contained the follow- ing principles : i) the limited liability of members ; 2) the State s minute in- spection of the management of the societes. These principles were however atteimated by parliament, and the law which has been in force since 28 March 1903 contains the following : i) All co-operative societies, whether credit or other, are legal corpo- rations. They may be formed on the basis of either unlimited or limited liability. Those of the first form enjoy however a preference under the law which declares them exempt from taxes. Co-operative societies founded on the principle of hmited liability are obliged to .subscribe a capital in shares of at least a thousand francs ; those founded on the principle of unlimited Hability can be formed without any capital in shares. 2) All the co-operative societies are subject to the inspection of the Agricultural Credit, that is to say of the Central Bank which was a section of the Agricultural Credit and is obliged to hold an inspection at least once 62 RUMANIA - CREDIT 3) A Central Bank was formed for the co-operative societies, as a section of the Agricultural Credit, and gives credit to the co-operative cre- dit societies. Since 1906 the Central Bank has been separated from the Agri- cultural Credit, and works as an autonomous institution. The law lays down conditions which the co-operative societies must fulfil in order to obtain credit from the Central Bank. These are as follows : i) a society must accept as members only the peasants of the village in which it is situated ; 2) the rate of interest it receives will be fi.'ced by the central bank ; 3) 10 per cent, of the net profits will be paid into a reserve fund. All these conditions show a desire to favour co-operative societies having unlimited liability. At first the Central Bank was, as we have said, attached to the Agricul- tural Credit ; i) because the latter had a very large capital at its disposal ; 2) because it had experience in the credit business transacted with peasants. Later, in 1906, when the Central Bank was separated from the Agricul- tural Credit, the special law prescribed that its working capital should be supplied by the Agricultural Credit. Of recent years there has been a movement towards forming district federations. Four of these have been formed ; one at Dumbraveni which unites ten co-operative societies and has a capital in shares of 27,000 francs, one at Fg. Bujor which comprises eighteen co-operative societies and has a capital in shares of 45,000 francs ; one at Topoloveni which has eleven co-operative societies and a capital in shares of 23,200 francs ; and one at Fg. Giacenea which has ten societies and a capital of 50,000 francs. The co-operative credit societies grant credit to their members, and also to outsiders who receive about one third of their loans. The loans are for long and for short terms: namely for from nine months to three years for the purchase of provisions, forage and seeds ; and for from three to ten years for that of live stock and agricultural implements and for the renting and purchase of land. The business of the co-operative societies furnishes the following figures, In 1902 there were 2,862 rural co-operative credit societies, having 563,270 members ; 99,067.74 francs of paid-up capital ; 7,151,799 francs in reserve funds ; 16,503,381 francs in deposits : and debts to the Central Bank of 11,447,529 francs. They had granted 138,652,562 francs in credit. This credit was distributed as follows : i) For provisions and forage 17.37 per cent ; for live stock and agricultural implements 32.34 per cent. ; for the purchase and renting of land 20.78 per cent. ; various 16.74 P^^ cent. 2) Personal credit amounted to 37.75 per cent, and credit on chattels to 62.25 per cent (27.33 per cent, on bills and 34.92 per cent, on pledgfes). 3) The fol- lowing shows the amounts of the credit granted ; 6.46 per cent, of the grants were of less than 50 francs; 18.62 per cent, were from 50 to 100 francs; 68.40 per cent, from 100. to 1000 francs; 6.52 per cent, more than 1000 francs. Part IV: Agricultural Economy in General UNITED STATES. IvAND TENURE AND THE ORGANIZATION OF AGRICULTURE ON INDIAN RESERVATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES prepared under the direction of Cato Sells, Commissioner of Indian Affairs. § I. lyAND TENURE. On June 30, 1916, there were 312,654 Indians in the United States under Federal supervision, occupying 174 reservations. Some of these reserv^ations were granted by Act of Congress, pursuant to treaties or agreements with the various tribes ; others were estabUshed by Executive Order of the President of the United States ; and several were acquired by still different methods, which will be explained hereafter. In the Pro- clamation of George III, dated October 7, 1763, four principles of govern- ment in Indian affairs, in force to the present day, were laid down : (i) The recognition of the Indian's right of occupancy : * * * " And whereas it is just and reasonable, and essential to our interest, and the security of our Colonies, that the several nations or tribes of Indians, with whom we are connected, and who live under our protection, should not be molested or disturbed in the possession of such parts of our do- minions and territories, as, not having been ceded to, or purchased by us, are reserved to them, or any of them, as their hunting grounds. (2) The right to expel ivhite intruders on Indian lands : * * * " All the lands and territories not included within the limits of our said three new Governments or within the limits of the territory granted to the Hudson's Bay Company ; as also all the lands and territories lying to the westward of the sources of the rivers which fall into the sea from the West and Northwest as aforesaid ; and we do hereby strictly forbid * * * * all * * * subjects from making * * * settlements * * * or taking posses- sion of any of the lands above reserved * * *. And we do further strict- ly enjoin and require all persons whatever, who have wilfully or inadver- tently seated themselves upon any lands within the counties above de- scribed, or upon any other lands, which have not been ceded to, or purchased 64 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY INT GENERAL by US, are still reserved to the said Indians as aforesaid, forthwith to remove themselves from such settlements. (3) The right to purchase Indian lands is vested solely in the govern- ment : * * * "We do, with the advice of our Privy Council, strictly enjoin and require that no private person do presume to make any purchase from the said Indians of any lands reserved to the said Indians * * * jf at any time any of the said Indians should be inclined to dispose of the said lands, the same shall be purchased only for us, in our name. (4) The right to regulate trade and license traders : * * * " Hvery person who may incline to trade with the said Indians, do take out a li- cense for carrying on such trade, from the Governor or Commander-in- chief of any of our colonies respectively * * * and also give security to observe such regulations as we shall at any time think fit * * * to direct and appoint for the benefit of the said trade ". The civiHzed nations of Europe which had acquired territory on this continent, asserted in themselves and recognized in others the exclusive right of the discoverer to appropriate the lands occupied by the Indians. By the Treat}'' of 1783, the United States acquired all the rights to the soil which had previously been in Great Britain ; by the Treaty of 1803, with France (the L,ouisiana purchase) it agreed to exe- cute and respect all treaties made or agreed upon between Spain and the several tribes of Indians residing within the territory ceded. The Su- preme Court of the United States, in an early decision, held that the Gov- ernment had a clear title to aU the lands within the areas referred to above, subject only to the Indian right of occupancy ; that the Indians had the unquestioned right to the lands they occupied until that right was voluntarily transferred by them to the Government ; that they occu- pied lands to which the United States held title, independent of their will which must take effect in respect to possession when their right of occu- pancy ceased ; and that the claim of the Governement extends to the complete ultimate title, charged with the Indian right of occupancy and possession, and to the exclusive power to acquire that right. r' During the colonial period, charters and grants were made by the Government, of land for the occupancy of Indians, known as their hunt- ing grounds. Their rights to its exclusive enjo^^ment in their own way and for their own purposes were always recognized by the colonists until abandoned or ceded by them, their right of occupancy being respected by the political power of the colony and upheld by the courts until extin- guished. Article 3, of the Act of July 13, 1787, entitled " An ordinance for the governement of the territory of the United States northwest of the river Ohio ", provides, in part, as follows : " The utmost good faith shall always be observed toward the Indians ; their land and property shall never be taken from them without their consent ; and in their property, rights and liberty they shall never be invaded or disturbed, unless in just and lawful wars authorized by Con- gress ; but laws founded in justice and humanity shall from time to time LAND TENURE AND THE ORGANIZATION OF AGRICULTURE 6 5 be made for preventing wrongs being done to them and for preserving peace and friendship with them ". Originall}^ the relations of the Government with the Indians were determined by treaties made with their tribal authorities. Although the Government claimed complete sovereignty over the territory and inhabitants within its limits, and while treaties, in the true legal sense of the term, can only be entered into between independent sovereignties, yet the colonies, and also the mother country, had treated with the In- dians as " nations ", their chiefs, or " sachems ", often being designated kings. This notion was retained by the founders of the Government and thus became its established policy. The early treaties generally defined the boundary line between the Indian country and that of the United States, which at first extended from the lake on the north to Florida on the south. The United States claimed no control over its citizens who ventured to pass this line. Gradually trading and military posts were established and the land about them se- cured from the Indians ; then roadways between these stations were ob- tained ; until finallj' the Indians were living upon defined tracts. The continued pressure of immigration and the consequent demand for land resulted in the Indians exchanging their more eastern tracts for reserva- tions, set apart for them by the Government in the western part of the countr>^ The establishment of such reservations was the natural result of the cession of their lands by the Indians to the United States, and was necessary in order to provide them with homes and with land for culti- vation ; to avoid disputes in regard to boundaries ; and to bring the In- dians more easily under the control of the Government by confining them within given areas. This policy involved a very important and radical change in the customs and habits of the Indians and was the first step by them toward agricultural pursuits as their principal means of livelihood, the organization and development of which form the subject of the second part of this article. The making of treaties with the Indians was terminated by the Act of March 3, 1871, as follows : " Hereafter no Indian tribe within the territory- of the States shall be accepted or recognized as an independent nation, tribe, or power, with whom the United States may contract by treaty. " The effect of this Act was to bring under the immediate control of Congress the relations of the Government with the Indians, and to reduce to simple agreements, subject to ratification by Congress, what had pre- viously been accomplished by formal and solemn treaties, as with a fo- reign power. However, this procedure accomplishes practically the same residts in a different manner more consonant with the real sover- eignty of the United States and the progress of civilization. After the passage of this law, reservations were created either by Act of Congress (generally in ratification of an agreement with the Indians) or by Executive Order of the President of the United States, either with or withoiTt the specific authority of Congress, such reservations being 66 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL sometimes authorized by Act of Congress and their limits subsequently- defined by Executive Order ; others were first established by Executive Order and later confirmed b}^ Act of Congress. This, however, is not necessary, as the President may, at his discretion, establish Indian reser- vations, on public lands not otherwise occupied, without the specific prior authority of Congress, or its subsequent ratification. The right of the Indians to their reservation is ordinarily subject to certain restrictions, as set forth by decision of the United States Supreme Court, a portion of which is quoted below : " The right of the Indians to the reservations ordinarily occupied by them is that of occupancy alone. The fee is in the United States, sub- ject only to this right of occupancy. The Indians have no power of alien- ation except to the United States. But while the fee to the reservations is in the United States, the right of the Indians to their use and occupancy'- is as sacred as that of the Government to the fee. They have the right to apply to their own use and benefit the entire products of the reserva- tion, whether the result of their own labour or of natural growth, so they do not commit waste. If the lands in a state of nature are not in a con- dition for profitable use they may be made so ; if desired for the purpose of agriculture the}^ may be cleared of their timber to such an extent as ma3^ be reasonable under the circumstances, and the surplus timber taken off by the Indians in such clearing, and not required for use on the pre- mises, may be sold by them. The Indians may cut growing timber for fuel and for necessary use upon the reservation ; they may open mines and quarry stone for the sole purpose of obtaining fuel and building mate- rial ; the^^ ma}^ cut hay for the use of their live stock, and may sell any stuplus not needed for that purpose. In short, what a tenant for life may do upon the lands of a remainder-man the Indians may do upon their reservation, but no more. " On the other hand, it is obligatory' upon the Government to prevent any intrusion, trespass, or settlement on the lands of any Indian tribe, unless such tribe has first given its consent thereto, either by treaty or agreement. In a few cases reseni^ations have been patented to certain tribes by the Government, such as the Cherokees, Choctaws, and Creeks. The construction given to such patents by the courts is that they are not titles in fee simple, for they convey no power of alienation except to the United States ; neither are they the same as the ordinary- title of occupancy ; thej^ are rather a " base, qualified, or determinable fee, with a possibility of reversion to the United States only ", and the Indians may cut, sell, or dispose of the timber, and permit mining and grazing witliin the limits of their respective tracts by their own citizens. In several cases the Indians have purchased the lands comprising their reservations, the title thereto being held in trust for their benefit by the Government tribal council, or other parties. At first the land was held in common for the benefit of all the Indians, each head of a family being allowed to cultivate and use a tract assigned to or selected by him, a certificate of occupancy sometimes being issued lyAND TENURE AND THE ORGANIZATION OF AGRICUIvTQRE 67 as evidence of his right thereto. This policy was continued until the pas- sage by Congress of the General Allotment Act on February 8, 1887, sev- eral sections of which are quoted below : (i) (As amended by the Acts of February 28, 1891 and June 25, 1910). " That in all cases where any tribe or band of Indians has been or shall hereafter be located upon any reservation created for their use by treaty stipulation, Act of Congress, or executive order, the President shall be authorized to cause the same or any part thereof to be survej^ed or resurveyed whenever in his opinion such reserv^ation or any part thereof may be advantageously utilized for agricultural or grazing purposes by such Indians, and to cause allotment to each Indian located thereon to be made in such areas as in liis opinion may be for their best interest, not to exceed eighty acres of agricultural or one hundred and sixty acres of grazing land to any one Indian. And whenever it shall appear to the President that lands on any Indian reser\^ation, subject to allotment by authority of law, have been or may be brought within any irrigation pro- ject, he may cause allotments of such irrigable lands to be made to the Indians entitled thereto in such areas as may be for their best interest, not to exceed, however, forty acres to any one Indian, and such irrigable land shall be held to be equal in quantity to twice the number of acres of non-irrigated agricultural land and four times the number of acres of non-irrigable grazing land : Provided, That the remaining area to which any Indian may be entitled under existing law, after he shall have received his proportion of irrigable land on the basis of equalization herein estab- lished, may be allotted to him from non-irrigable agricidtural or grazing lands : Provided fttrther, .That where a treaty or Act of Congress setting apart such reservation provides for allotments in severalty in quantity greater or less than that herein authorized, the President shall cause allot- ments on such reservations to be made in quantity as specified in such treaty or Act, subject, however, to the basis of equalization between irri- gable and non-irrigable lands established herein, but in such cases allot- ments may be made in quantity as specified in this Act, with the consent of the Indians expressed in such maimer as the President in his discretion may require. (5) " That upon the approval of the allotments provided for in this Act by the Secretary of the Interior, he shall cause patents to issue therefor in the name of the allottees, which patents shall be of the legal effect, and declare that the United vStates does and will hold the land thus allotted, for the period of twenty-five A^ears, in trust for the sole use and benefit of the Indian to whom such allotment shall have been made, or, in the case of his decease, of his heirs according to the laws of the State or Tevritory where such land is located, and that at the expiration of said period the United States will convey the same bj^ patent to said Indian, or his heirs as aforesaid, in fee, discharged of said trust and free of all charge or incumbrance whatsoever ; Provided, That the President of the United States may in any case in his discretion extend the period. And if any conveyance shall be made of the lands set apart and allotted as herein 68 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAI. ECONOMY IN GENERAL provided, or any contract made touching the same, before the expiration of the time above mentioned, such conveyance or contract shall be abso- lutely null and void : Provided, That the law of descent and partition in force in the .State or Tenitory where such lands are situate shall apply thereto after patents therefor have been executed and deUvered, except as herein otherwise provided ; and the laws of the State of Kansas regu- lating the descent and partition of real estate shall, so far as practicable, apply to all lands in the Indian Territory which may be allotted in severalty under the provisions of this Act : And provided further, that at any time after lands have been allotted to all the Indians of any tribe as herein provided, or sooner if in the opinion of the President it shall be for the best interests of said tribe, it shall be lawful for the Secretary of the Interior to negotiate wdth such Indian tribe for the purchase and release by said tribe, in conformity with the treaty or statute under which such reservation is held, of such portions of its reservation not allotted as such tribe shall, from time to time, consent to sell, on such terms and conditions as shall be considered just and equitable between the United States and said tribe of Indians, which purchase shall not be complete until ratified by Congress, and the form and manner of executing such release shall also be prescribed by Congress. (6) (■ As amended by the Act of May 8, 1906). " That at the expi- ration of the trust period and when the lands have been conveyed to the Indians by patent in fee, as provided in section five of this Act, then each and every -allottee shall have the benefit of and be subject to the laws, both civil and criminal, of the vState or Territory in which they may reside ; and no Territory shall pass or enforce any law denying any such Indian within its jurisdiction the equal protection of the law. And evers^ Indian born mthin the territorial limits of the United States to whom allot- ments shall have been made and who has received a patent in fee simple under the provi.sions of this Act, or under any law or treaty, and every Indian born within the territorial limits of the United States who has voluntarily taken up within said limits his residence, separate and apart from any tribe of Indians therein, and has adopted the habits of civihzed life, is hereby declared to be a citizen of the United States, and is entitled to all the rights, privileges, and immunities of such citizens, whether said Indian has been or not, by birth or otherwise, a member of any tribe of Indians within the territorial limits of the United States without in any manner impairing or otherwise affecting the right of any such Indian to tribal or other property : Provided, That the Secretary of the Interior may, in his discretion, and he is hereby authorized, whenever he shall be satisfied that any Indian allottee is competent and capable of managing his or her affairs, at any time to cause to be issued to such allottee a pa- tent in fee simple, and thereafter all restrictions as to sale, incumbrance, or taxation of said land shall be removed and said land shall not be liable to the satisfaction of any debt contracted prior to the issuing of such pa- tent : Provided further, That until the issuance of fee-simple patents all allottees to whom trust patents shall hereafter be issued shall be I,AND TENURE AND THE ORGANIZATION OF AGRICULTURE 69 subject to the exclusive jurisdiction of the United States : And -pro- vided further, That the provisions of this Act shall not extend to any Indians in the Indian Territory. " That hereafter when an allotment of land is made to any Indian, and any such Indian dies before the expiration of the trust period, such allotment shall be cancelled and the land shall revert to the United vStates, and the Secretary of the Interior shall ascertain the legal heirs of such Indian, and shall cause to be issued to said heirs and in their names, a patent in fee simple for said land, or he may cause the land to be sold as provided by law and issue a patent therefor to the purchaser or purcha- sers, and pay the net proceeds to the heirs, or the legal representatives, of such deceased Indian. The action of the Secretary of the Interior in determining the legal heirs of any deceased Indian, as provided herein, shall in all respects be conclusive and final ". The terms of such patents transnritting title to the Indian allottee, first in trust, and then in fee simple, as provided by the Act, are as follows. Trust. "Whereas, a schedule of allotments approved by the Secretary of the Interior has been deposited in the General I^and Office, whereby it ap- pears that John Smith, a Flathead Indian, has been allotted the following described land : Northwest quarter of the southeast quarter of Section twenty-seven, township six, north, range thirteen west, Montana princi- pal meidian. "Now Know Ye, that the United States of America, in Consideration of the Premises, has allotted, and by these presents does allot, unto the said Indian the land above described, and hereby declares that it does and will hold the land thus allotted (subject to all statutory provisions and restrictions) for the period of twenty-five years, in trust for the sole use and benefit of the said Indian ; and at the expiration of said period, the United States will convey the same by patent to said Indian in fee, discharged of said trust and free from all charge and incumbrance whatsoever ; but in the event said Indian dies before the expiration of said trust period the vSecretary of the Interior shall ascertain the legal heirs of said Indian and either issue to them in their names a patent in fee for said land or cause said land to be sold for the benefit of said heirs as provided by law ; and there is reserved from the lands hereb}^ allotted a right of way thereon for ditches or canals constructed by the authority of the United States. Fee. " Whereas, an order of the Secretary of the Interior has been deposit- ed in the General Land Office directing that a fee simple patent issue to the claimant, John Smith, a Flathead Indian, for the Northwest quarter of the southeast quarter of section twenty-seven, township six, north, range thirteen west, Montana principal meridian. 70 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMV IX GENERAL "Now Know Ye, that the United States of America, in consideration of the premises, has given and granted, and by these presents does give and grant unto the said claimant and to the heirs of the said claimant, the land above described, to have and to hold the same together with all the rights, privileges, immunities, and appurtenances of whatsoever nature thereunto belonging, unto the said claimant and to the heirs and assignees of the said claimant, forever ; and there is reserved from the lands hereby granted a right of way thereon for ditches or canals constructed by the authority of the United States ". Sections 4 and 5 of the Act of June 25, 1910, provide as follows : " (4) That any Indian allotment of any Indian held under a trust patent may be leased by the allottee for a period not to exceed five years, subject to and in conformity with such rules and regulations as the Sec- retary of the Interior may prescribe, and the proceeds of any such lease shall be paid to the allottee or his heirs, or expended for his or their benefit, in the discretion of the Secretary of the Interior. " (5) That it shall be unlawftd for any person to induce any Indian to execute any contract, deed, mortgage, or other instrument purport- ing to convey any land or any interest therein held by the United States in trust for such Indian, or to offer any such contract, deed, mortage or other instrument for record in the office of any recorder of deeds. Any person violating this provision shall be deemed guilty of a misdemeanour, and upon conviction shall be punished by a fine not exceeding five hundred dollars for the first offence, and if convicted for a second offence may be punished by a fine not exceeding five hundred dollars or imprisonment, not exceeding one year, or by both such fine and imprisonment, in the discretion of the court : Provided, That this section shall not appty to any lease or other contract authorized by laws to be made ". In brief, this Act provides for the allotment of land in- severalty to each individual Indian, in the quantitj^ specified, for the different classes; for the issuance to said Indian of a trust patent, as evidence thereof, to run twenty-five years ; that at the expiration of this period, unless exten- ded (or sooner, within the discretion of the Secretary of the Interior), a fee patent shall be issued to the allottee, removing said land from Govern- ment control ; that any conveyance or hypothecation thereof during the trust period is void ; and that, upon being given the fee patent, the In- dian becomes a citizen of the State in which he lives, and subject to all the laws thereof (previously thereto having been under the exclusive jurisdiction of the United States). Under Sections 4 and 5 of the Act of June 25, 1910, above quoted, an Indian holding a trust patent may lease his land, with the approval of the Secretary of the Interior, the proceeds thereof being paid to said In- dian if competent or expended for his benefit if incompetent. It is also made unlawful to induce any Indian holding a trust patent to execute any contract, deed or mortgage with respect thereto. An Indian holding a trust patent may sell his land or devise it b^^ will, with the approval of the Secretary of the Interior. LAND TENURE AND THE ORGANfZATlON OF AGRICULTURE 7I According to the latest figures there are 312,654 Indians in the United States under Federal supervision, who inhabit 174 reservations compris- ing 70,891,091 acres of land. Under the general allotment Act, as amended, 211,172 allotments of land in severalty have been made to individual Indians, aggregating 34,477,970 acres, and trust patents issued there- for as above set forth. Of this number, 72,508 Indians now hold trust patents and 112,357 l^^^d ^^^ patents. Since 1902, sales have been effected of 11,752 individual tracts of allotted Indian land, comprising 1,405,463 acres, for a total of $22,015,907. § 2. The ORGANIZATION OF AGRICULTURE. Almost without exception the early explorers found the Indians in what is now the United States, from the border of the Western plains to the Atlantic Ocean, dwelling in settled villages and cultivating the soih De Soto found all the tribes visited by him from the Florida peninsula to the Western part of Arkansas cultivating maize and other food plants. The esLtly voyagers found the same thing true along the Atlantic Coast from Florida to Massachusetts. Captain John Smith and his James- town colony, indeed aU the early colonies, depended at first very largety for food supplies upon the products of Indian cultivation. Jacques Car- tier, the first European to ascend the St. Lawrence River, found the In- dians cultivating the soil. " They have ", he says, good and large fields of corn. " Champlain and other early French explorers testify to the great reliance of the Iroquois on the cultivation of the soil for food. La vSalle observed the Indians cultivating and to a large extent subsisting on maize. Besides maize, beans, squashes, pumpkins, sweet potatoes, and tobacco were cultivated to a considerable extent, especially in what are now the Southern States. Marquette, speaking of the Illinois Indians, says that, in addition to maize, " they also sow beans and melons, which are excellent, especialty those with the red seed ". In regard to the tribes further West an early writer states, " From the earliest information we have of the Pueblo Indians they are known to have been tillers of the soil, and though the implements used and their methods of cultivation were both simple and primitive, cotton, corn, wheat (after its introduction), beans and many varieties of fruit were grown in abundance. The Indians of Arizona and New Mexico had learnt the art of irri- gating their fields before the appearance of the white man on the conti- nent. This is shown not only by the statements of the early explorers but also by the stiU existing remains of their ditches, estimated to have been sufficient for the irrigation of at least 250,000 acres. There is definite evidence that the Indians used fertilizers although it has been stated that they did not. The Plymouth colonists were told by Indians to add fish to the old grounds. It is also stated that the Iroquois manured their land. Lescarbot says that the Virginia Indians and others 72 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL " enrich their fields with shells and fish ". The implements they used in cultivating the ground are described by him as " wooden howes and spades made of hard wood ". " The Florida Indians dig their ground with an implement of wood fashioned like a broad mattox ; they use howes made of the shoulder blades of animals fixed on staves ; and a piece of wood three inches broad, bent at one end and fastened to a long handle, suffices them to free the land from weeds and turn it up lightly " Among the Indians the farm and field work was mostly done by the women, the men being regarded as hunters and warriors. Hariot says (1810) : " The women, with short pickers or parers (because they use them sitting) of a foot long and about five inches in breadth, do ovly break the upper part of the ground to raise up the weeds, grass and old stubs or corn stalks with their roots. " It was a general custom to burn over the ground before planting in order to free it from weeds and rubbish. In the forest region patches were cleared by girdling the trees, thus causing them to die and afterwards burning them down. While the women were thus occupied, the men en- gaged in fishing, hunting, or trapping, when not busA^ on the war path. The first treaty between the United States and any Indian tribe was made with the Delawares on September 17, 1778, and was concerned primarily with the establishment and preservation of peace between the the whites and Indians and the recognition by the latter of the authority of the United States. No grants of money or food supplies to Indians were made therein, but this practice gradually developed in subsequent treaties, manj^ of which also included an agreement on the part of the Indians to remain within a certain restricted locaHty, this being the germ of the present reserv^ation system. Apparently the first treaty in which the United States specifically agreed to furnish farmers to instruct the Indians in agricultural pursuits was that with the Menominee Indians on February 8, 1831, as follows : " The above reservation being made to the Menominee Indians, for the purpose of weaning them from their wandering habits by attach- ing them to comfortable homes, the President of the United States, as a mark of affection for his children of the Menominee tribe, will cause to be employed five farmers of established character for capacity, industry and moral habits, for ten successive years, whose duty it shall be to in- struct the Menominee Indians in the cultivation of their farms and to in- struct their children in the business and occupation of farming. " The first general appropriation for Indian education was made on March, 3, 1819, when an Act was passed appropriating $10,000 as follows : " For the purpose of providing against the further decline and final extinction of the Indian tribes adjoining the frontier settlements of the United States, and for introducing among them the habits and arts of civ- ilization, the President of the United States shall be, and he is hereby, au- thorized, in every case where he shall judge improvement in the habits L-AND TENURE AND THE ORGANIZATION Ol' AGRICUI^TURE 73 and condition of such Indians practicable, and that the means of instruc- ction can be introduced with their own consent, to employ capable per- sons of good moral character to instruct them in the mode of agriculture suited to their situation ; and for teaching their children in reading, writ- ing and arithmetic, and performing such other duties as may be enjoined, according to such instructions and rules as the President may give and prescribe for the regulation of their conduct in the discharge of their duties ". At the present time the Office of Indian Affairs is a bureau of the Department of the Interior, and is presided over by an official known as the Commissioner of Indian Affairs. Each reservation is directly in charge of a bonded superintendent, who is responsible to the Commis- sioner for the proper and efficient conduct of the affairs of the Indians on his particular reservation, including their agricultural operations. Most of the reservations are divided into districts, each in charge of a farmer who resides therein and is furnished with transportation equip- ment in order that he may travel about and instruct the Indians in their agricultural work. This farmer must be personally acquainted with every Indian famih' in his district and thoroughly familiar with their industrial condition, needs and resources, so as to assist them to get the best results from their labours. The farmers are appointed from a register of eUgibles who have passed the required Civil Service examination, in order to test their fitness for the particular work devolving upon them. They make frequent verbal and written reports to the Superintendent as to agricul- tural conditions in their respective districts, and the Superintendents submit regular annual reports to the Commissioner, besides such special reports from time to time as conditions may warrant. That portion of the United States in which Indian reservations are located is divided into ten supervisory districts, each of which is assigned to an inspecting official, who makes periodical trips to the various reser- vations in his territory, for the purpose of determining and reporting upon the agricultural progress of the Indians and aU other matters relating to the administration of their affairs. By means of such reports, the Com- missioner is kept informed as to actual conditions, the degree of efficiency of the various Superintendents, farmers, and other employees, as a basis for such administrative action as he may deem necessars\ The present appropriation for agricultural work among the Indians reads as follows : " For the employment of practical farmers and stockmen, in ad dition to the agency and school farmers now employed ; for necessary traveUing expenses of such farmers and stockmen, and for furnishing ne- cessary equipment and supphes for them ; and for superintending and di- recting farming and stock-raising among Indians. " Two hundred and fifty eight farmers are now employed and paid from this appropriation or other available funds. The statement given below shows the number of Indians farnoing, 1 lie total cultivated acreage, the average acreage per Indian, and the value 74 UNITED STATES - AGRICUIyTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL of crops produced by the Indians each year since 191 1, when the present statistical system was inaugurated : No. Indians Farming Acreage Average Cultivated per Indian Value of Crops Raised 1911 I912 I913 1914 1915 IQ16 24,489 383.025 15.6 28,051 558,503 19.9 29,216 595.331 20.4 2Q,8lI 594,268 19.9 31,956 664,539 20.8 35,823 678,527 19.0 $ 1,951,672 3,250,288 4,021,392 4,007,335 4,790,968 5,293,719 While it is preferred that the Indians purchase their own farming implements, seed, etc., yet where they lack the necessary individual funds for this purpose, liie Government furnishes them with such supplies, in return for labour by the individual for the benefit of the tribe (on the reser- vation roads, bridges, etc.) to be paid for in cash in easy instalments on what is known as the reimbursable plan, explained below ; or, in the case of seed, to be returned in kind at harvest. Ordinarily the Government purchases articles of this kind in large quantities so as to get the benefit of lower prices, and then distributes them to the individual Indians on the conditions above set forth. Every Indian receiving property on the reimbursable plan must sign an agreement substantially as follows : " Agreement entered into this tenth day of July, 1915, between John Smith of the Apache tribe of Indians, and F. W. Jones, superin- tendent and special disbursing officer for and on behalf of the United States of America, covering property, stock, or equipment purchased under the provisions of the Act of Congress dated May 18, 1914 from ' Industry Among Indians, 1915 '. "It is hereby agreed that John Smith will pay to F. W. Jones, or his successors in office, the sum of One Hundred Dollars ($100), in payments to be made as hereinafter mentioned, which payments are to be in full consideration for the property, stock or equipment, listed below, and receipt for which is hereby acknowledged by John Smith. I farm wagon $ 100.00 Total $ 100.00 LAND TENURE AND TilE ORGANIZATION OF AGRICULTURE 75 " Payments to be made by said John Smith to the said F. W. Jones, or his successors in office, as follows : Date due Jan. 10, 1916 ,• • • • $ 25.00 July 10, 1916 25.00 Jan. 10, 1917 25.00 Jtily 10, 1917 25.00 Total ... $ 100.00 " It is stipulated and agreed that the title to the above-described ar- ticles shall remain in the United States of America until payment in full has been made, and that in default of payment, or in case of failure to properly care for or have cared for,' or use the same, the said superinten- dent, or his successors in office, shall take possession of said property as set forth in regulations approved by the Secretary of the Interior Octo- ber 6, 1914. "It is further stipulated and agreed that upon payment in full by John Smith of the amount of consideration named, that the title, free and unencumbered, of the articles mentioned shall pass to said John Smith- (Signed) John Smith. Many of the reservations are best adapted to the live stock industry rather than farming. From the latest figures it appears that the Indians of the United States under Federal supervision own individually $ 26,703,027 worth of Hve stock in addition to tribal stock held in common, valued at approximately $2,121,412 ; Indians to the number of 43,309 being engag- ed in the live stock industry. In addition to the farmers, there are also employed fifty -three superintendents of live stock and stockmen who are charged with the responsibility for the successful conduct of this in- dustry on sound business principles. While the Indian Bureau is not under the jurisdiction of the United States Department of Agriculture, but maintains its own distinctive agricultural oganization under the direction of the Commissioner of Indian Affairs, yet the officials and employees of that department have voluntarily placed their facilities at the disposal of this office for the benefit of the Indians wher- ever practicable. The Indians are further instructed in all the details of successful modern farming by stereopticon lectures by experts from the United States Department of Agriculture or the State agricidtural college under a co-operative plan inaugurated two years ago ; and through the medium of boys' and girls'agricultural clubs ; and their interest and enthu- siasm are developed by holding agricultural fairs where they exihibit their products in open competition with each other, suitable prizes being given, or in competition at conveniently located county or State fairs. Most of the reservation fairs are managed entirely by the Indians (under the supervision of the superintendent), who have organized associations for 76 UNITED STATES - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL this purpose. On many of the reservations the Indians also maintain farmers' clubs organized with a view to promoting their agricultural welfare. The principal concern of the Ser\dce at the present stage of. Indian progress is to make them producers instead of merely consumers, from which it necessarily follows that the greatest strength of its agricultural organization has been directed toward production rather than distribution. Therefore, no particular organization is maintained for the specific purpose of marketing Indian agricultural products, each Indian being permitted to dispose of his surplus crops wherever he pleases. The Superintendent, however, may advise them with respect to the best markets and must see that they obtain fair prices for their products. Schoolroom instruction is given the Indian boys in the theory and principles of modern agriculture, which they must then apply in actual practice on individual tracts of land assigned to them on a farm maintained for this purpose, the crops produced being utilized for the partial support of the school. The related subject of honae economics among the Indian women is given much attention, involving, as it does, the preparation of food from the products of the soil, a force of sixty-eight field matrons being employed to instruct the Indian women in all that pertains to successful home- making and healthful living, particularly the preparation and ser^dng of food. Theoretical and practical instruction on such topics is also given the Indian girls while at school. Quantity and Value of Crops Produced by Indians. Fiscal Year 1916. Produce Average Value Total Alfalfa hay, etc Barley and rye Com Oats Wheat . . . . Vegetables . . . 237,605 231,498 1,117,797 1,471,020 1,430,830 Tons S 8.05 Bushels .80 Bushels •45 Bushels .32 Bushels ■95 — — $ 2,032,641 185,108 503,010 470,726 1,359,288 742.856 Total S 5,293,719 GREAT BRITAIN AND IRELAND. AGRICITLTURAL LABOUR IN IRELAND AND THE MIGRATION OF IRISH AGRICULTURAL LABOURERS. OFFICIAIy SOURCE : Report and Tables relating to Irish Agricultural 1,aboui?ers, presented to the I- considerable, b) The Places from which there is Migration. More details are obtained from the returns by the police enumerators of agricultural districts made in June of each year, as to the persons who had then migrated or who intended to migrate. These returns. include only about 60 per cent, of those who actually migrated, yet the}'- may be taken as typical ; and the following figures, ab- stracted from these returns, as to the number of persons emigrating from each province, may therefore be considered as giving the proportion in which the migrants were distributed over the provinces. 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 From Connaught » Ulster 6,848 1,824 168 38 6.867 2,097 230 23 6,547 1,988 136 16 5,438 1,735 145 23 5,258 1,845 » Munster 204 » I/Cinster 47 Total . . . 8,878 9,217 8,687 7,341 7,354 80 GREAT BRITAIN AVTD IRELAND - AGRICULTTJRAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL As regards only nien over twenty years of age, it is calculated that the migration rate in 1915 for all Ireland was 5.3 per 1,000 ; for Connaught it was 27.2, for Ulster 3.8, for Munster 0.5 and for Leinster o.i. The coun- ties having the highest migration rates were Mayo 74.1 pen, 000, Donegal 30.5 per 1,000, Roscommon 13.7 per 1,000, and vSligo and Galway 7.0 per 1,000. In one Connaught county, Leitrim, the migrants numbered only I.I per 1,000. From the Poor law Union returns, which concern women and men of all ages, the facts as to migration can be further localized. The highest migration rate in Ireland in 1915 was in Swinford union in County Mayo where 42 out of ever}^ 1000 inhabitants migrated. The next highest rates were 31.9 per 1,000 in Dunfanaghy, Co. Donegal ; 29.8 per 1,000 in Westport, Co. Mayo ; 28.2 in Glenties, Co. Donegal ; 25.0 in Belmullet, Co. Mayo ; 19.1 in Castlebar, Co. Mayo ; 16.7 in Claremorris, Co. Mayo ; 12.4 in Castle- reagh, Co. Roscommon ; and 10.6 in Glennamadd3^ Co. Galway. The following figures, taken from the returns of the police enumerators, show the proportion of women who migrated each year to be unimportant. 1911 1912 19 1 3 1914 1915 8,545 8,789 8,394 7,112 6,927 Women 333 428 293 229 427 Total 9,217 8,687 7.341 7.354 c) The Classes of the Migrants. As regards the classes from which migrants are d,ra'wn 6,338 or 86 per cent, of those included in the returns of the jiolice enumerators for 1915 belonged to the class of landholders — 1,578 being themselves landhold- ers, ^,372 landholders' sons and 388 landholders' daughters. Of the land- holders 227 had holdings whichdid not exceed 5 acres, 587 held from 5 to 10 acres; 425 from 10 to 15 acres ; 166 from 15 to 20 acres ; 78 from 20 to 25 acres ; 35 from 25 to 30 acres ; 23 from 30 to ^o acres ; and 37 more than 40 acres. The larger holdings were chiefly rough grazing land and mountain land of low value. d) The Places to which there is Migration. The following table shows the percentages of the total number of mi- grant labourers from 1911 to 1915 who went, respectively, to England and Wales, Scotland, and Irish districts other than those in which they had their permanent home. i,abot;r and the migration' of irish agricultural labourers 8 1 England and Wales 1911 73-2 ICJI2 , 65.8 1913 70-9 19I4 69.4 1915 I 64.9 Scotland 22.0 27-3 237 27.0 30.0 Irish countries 4-8 6.9 5-4 3-6 51 Total loo.o lOO.O lOU.O loo.o lOO.O 4,776 migrants were enumerated as going to England in 1915 and 4,584 of them came from Conuaiight — 3,706 or 78 per cent, from County Mayo alone. After haymaking in Lancashire and Yorkshire they usually find further employment in these counties at turnip hoeing etc. The}' then move to Lincolnshire and North Cambridgeshire for the corn harvest, and thence to Warwickshire, Staffordshire and Cheshire for potato digging. In 1915 their usual wage was about 25s a week, in addition to free lodging and fuel and an allowance of potatoes and milk or beer. At piece work they earned as much as 35s or even 40s a week. The migrants enumerated as going to Scotland in 1915 numbered 2,205 > and of these 1,579 were from Ulster, and 622 from Connaught — including 1,538 or 70 per cent, of the whole number from County Donegal and 565 or 26 per cent, from County Mayo. The}' were chiefly engaged on potato lifting, on which some of them spent twenty weeks. As a rule they start work in Ayrshire early in June and scatter over the country later in the sea- son, and they return to Ireland in November. In 1915 they usually earned from aliout 25s to 306' a week, together with free lodging and fuel and some- times an allowance of potatoes. On piece work they made as much as 35s a week. English and Scottish employers bear testimony to the trustworthi- ness, skill and thrift of the migrants. They generally save from half to three quarters of their earnings and sometimes take as much as £20 home with them. The amount of their earnings and the rates of agricultural wages in Ireland, as these have been set out, go far to explain the continued migra- tion in spite of the scarcity of labour in Ireland. SWEDEN. CONDITIONS OF LIFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS OF VARMLAND, DALECARLIA and NORRIvAND. OFFICIAIv SOURCE: Skogsarbeiarnas levnads och arbetsforhAllanden : Varmland, Dalarna och NORRLANTJ. (Conditions of Life and Work among the Foresters in Vdrmland, Dalecarlia, and Sorrland, Stockholm, 1916. Introduction. On the occasion of a proposal made during the session of 1912, the Riksdag asked the government to have a report drawn up, as soon as pos- sible, on the position of foresters and the conditions of their life in Norrland and in districts similarly circumstanced from the point of view of forestry. The government was further requested to take such subsequent measures as the report rendered advisable, laying the necessary proposals before the Riksdag if appeal to this body should be necessar5^ The government commissioned the Administration of Commerce to make this report and bring forward the necessar)^ proposals. To discharge such a task it was requisite first to make a profound and impartial enquiry into the social and econoirdc conditions in which this numerous class of workmen live and work. This enquiry was prepared and begun b}' the Administration of Commerce after consultation with compe- tent persons, specially summoned ; and was completed by the Ro5^al Ad- ministration of Labour and Social Thrift, on which body the earher duties of the Labour Office, a department of the Administration of Com- merce, were incumbent after 1913. The report embraces not only Norrland but also the northern districts of Dalecarlia and Varmland, in which the conditions of the foresters' lives are analogous to those in Norrland ; and it concerns not only the foresters proper but also the men employed on floating timber, charcoal burning and such tasks. Its material has been collected by means of several diffe- rent statistical enquiries. In order to obtain an inclusive \4ew and to dis- cover the general conditions of life and work among the men employed in the forests within the whole sphere of the enquiry, a system was organized of consulting a large number of official doctors, inspectors of forests, asso- ciations of employers and of labourers in the forest industry, and delegates of the comnumes nominated by the societies of rural economy. From this combination of official authorities, associations and competent persons 615 answers were received to a special form of questions. On the basis of the CONDITIONS OF LIFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 83 general data thus collected detailed descriptions of certain more limited parts of the zone of enquiry were established. Thus 173 forest holdings and ten charcoalburners' yards, which employed respectively, 8,360 and 151 work- men, were selected on the proposal of the departmental and forest admini- strations and the chief inspectors of forests, as offering types of the different natural and local conditions and the different methods of forestry; and in these in February' and March 1913 an enquiry' was made by some fifty spe- cial agents who collected on the spot, following a detailed questionnaire, data as to the conditions of work, housing and feeding. As regarded certain forest domains taken to be typical, additional individual data, on the subject of the working hours, the wages and the personal confiition of all the employ- ees, were furnished by the respective employers according to a special form. The report, which is mainly based on material thus obtained, first treats of the conditions, the development and the present position of the forest industry in North Sweden. In this connection emphasis is laid on the abrupt and the profound transformation of the whole economic and social life of the population, and similarly of methods of cultvation, owing to the rapid development of the timber industry within a short space of time, that is within two or three generations. It is remarked that in this cirumstance must be sought the origin of the ver}^ complicated social problems, which under the name of the " questions of Norrland " have latterly attracted much attention from the public and from the government. Among these problems is that of the forest workpeople, and it is connected with the problem of improving conditions of life among this most important class of society to which belong, more or less, the whole male rural population of Northern Sweden, some 150,000 persons. § I. The Exploitation of the forests. The legal person, whether individual or corporation, who is the true ulti- mate employer of labour on forest holdings is the landowner. Often, how- ever, the landowner sells the standing timber, which is then exploited not on his behalf but on that of the purchaser, who thus becomes the employer, properly so-called. The difference is very important to conditions of work, for it is in the nature of things that a limited liability company, for example, should have more desire and ability to ensure good conditions to its forest labourers, when there is question of a long projected tree-felling within its forests, than when the question is one of making the quickest possible use of a purchased right of exploitation. In 48 per cent, of the hokUngs covered by the enquiry' the owner of the timber was also the landowner ; in 52 per cent, he was not. Of the forest workmen 62 per cent, were employed by land- owners exploiting their own forests and 38 per cent, by purchasers of timber. As regards the different categories of owners of woods the enquiry shows that the State and the communes have never practised tree-felling except on their own lands, and that rural landowners have done so on land not their own only exceptionally. Companies have however cut down purchased 84 SWEDEN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL woods as often, and timber merchants three times as often, as their own woods. On forest holdings the landowning employer is generally represented by keepers or other employees ; but such supervisors are too few to be able to exercise over workmen scattered over large forest areas the effective con- trol possible in manufacturing industries. This is the defective side of the organization of work in the forest industry, and gives it quite another aspect than manufacturing industries ; but on the other hand the rural po- pulation of Northern Sweden enjoy the advantage of a strong business sense and show a much developed spirit of initiative. The carters form the most important category of forest labourers, each of them being responsible for one or more of the lots forming sections. The woodcutters and other labourers — the loaders, the roadmakers, etc. — should properly be considered as carters' assistants for they are most fre- quently engaged and paid by the carters. As regards the proportionate size of the different groups of labourers, the enquiry shows that of a total number of 8,360 the carters form one third, the woodcutters rather more than a half, and labourers of other kinds about a sixth. But the proportion in the different departments deviates consi- derably from this average, partly owing to differences in the method of work. The facts which have been collected give some information as to the age and civil status of the workmen. Ninety -two per cent, were found to be over eighteen years old ; the large majority of the 8 per cent., who were under that age, being employed as woodcutters. Of the total number of adult workmen 52.7 percent, were bachelors, and 47.3 percent, married men, widowers or divorced men ; these percentages being 32.1 and 67.9 in the case of the carters, 65.6 and 34.4 in that of the woodcutters, and 55.4 and 44.6 in that of the other workmen.. The differences in these percentages are closely connected with the unequal distribution of men of the same age in the several categories of workmen, but are also due to the fact that the workmen are derived in very varying proportions from the different clas- ses of society. If the extent to which the three chief classes of the population — the landowning cultivators, the leaseholders and the labourers — are represent- ed on forest holdings in the various districts be examined, the following results are obtained : Depart- Dcnart Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Total meut Zone of of Norr- Enquiry botten ( Landowners (Hit 1)1 100 V Wdrkinen Ltaseholders there were V ' Liibourers nient meut ment meut ment of of of of of Varm- Koppar- Oiivle- Vaster- Jam- land berg < bor^ nofrlaud tlaud 47-7 16.3 36.0 63.1 17.0 19.9 18.3 20.6 61. 1 38.2 158 46.0 35-5 10.5 54-0 ment of Vastcr- botten 52.6 21.9 25-5 55-6 412 13-3 170 31. 1 41.8 It is seen that the deviations from the general averages in the several departments were considerable ; and as — at least in forest districts — the CONDITIONS OF IJFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 85 rural population regularly seek winter employment in the forests, the de- partmental averages reflect to some extent the different composition of the population in the several districts. If all the departments be considered together it is found that the land- owning cultivators who take part in exploiting the forests together with their families belong as to 69 per cent, to the local population while 31 per cent, are strangers. The leaseholders and their sons are domiciled as to 67.9 per cent, on lands belonging to the owners of the wood, as to 32.1 per cent, on lands in other ownership. In the general group of labourers three subdivisions can be distinguished: 41.4 per cent, who work- ed in the forests all the j^ear round, 44.5 per cent, who in certain seasons were employed on agriculture, and 14.1 per cent, who were employed on the forest industrj' for periods of time (craftsmen etc) . If the proportion in which special occupations are peculiar to certain social groups be examined, it is found that of the landowners and lease- holders, respectively, 43.0 per cent, and 48.9 per cent were carters, 42.4 per cent, and 36.9 per cent, woodcutters, while 14.6 per cent, and 14.2 per cent, followed other special trades. In the group of labourers the corresponding percentages were 12.8, 66.9 and 20.3. A carter, as has been said, is usually responsible for the exploitation of a forest lot; and may therefore be assum- ed to have a certain authority and economic independence ; very rare in the class of simple labourers, and found rather among the landowners and leaseholders, and especially among such of them as have reached a cer- tain age and position. Generally the carters manage farms large enough to support horses. They employ as woodcutters and for other labour their own sons and their sons-in law and farm-servants iii the first place, then their relatives, friends and neighbours. Usually they avoid engaging unknown journeymen workmen, for these are considered to be untrustworthy and likely to trouble the friendly and confidential relations between a carter and his assistants which are an indispensable condition of good and profit- able work. The amount of the revenue now derived from forestry in North Sweden, in spite of the inadequate number of the supervisors, is largely due to the fact that this industry is served by numerous bodies of workmen among whom there is this good understanding between chiefs and subordi- nates. The prevalent conditions have not failed to affect the labour contracts customary on forest holdings. These are usualh^ in writing : they were so in the case of 157 (90.8 per cent.) of the holdings covered by the enquiry and 88.4 per cent, of all the workmen. In 1.7 per cent, of the places inves- tigated contracts were made with outside employers, in 19.7 per cent, with one or more carters commissoned by the others, in 68.2 per cent, with all the carters, and in 1.2 per cent, with the carters and woodcutters together. The report gives a detailed account of the terms of contracts, reproducing a certain number of them as being typical. It treats of complaints made as to some of their provisions, as for example those concerned with the system of fines, the form of engaging woodcutters,tlie liability of carters for accidents 86 SWEDEN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL attendant on labour, the effect of the system of contracts on the price of labour, etc. Tree felling takes place principally in winter and the duration of the forestry season depends consequently in the first place on the very variable duration of the snow in different places. It is influenced also by many other circumstances, as by the greater or less amount of local forest enterprise, local customs, etc. In the whole zone of enquiry it may be said that there is a normal forest exploitation season of seventeen weeks or four months, a little less in the more southern and the coast regions and a little more in the north and in the forest regions of the interior. It must however be possible only quite exceptionally to carry on the work on all the working da5'^s of this period, which should rather be looked upon as the season in the gross. Farmwork, hoHdays on feastdays, journeys to get provisions and for other reasons, all take time which must be deducted from the actual working days of a forest exploiting season, which actually is far from attaining to its maximum length but covers from fifty to a hun- dred days. As regards the average number of working hours in a day these are usually seven or eight in the first part of the season, hours of rest being deducted. When in February the days become lighter the net hours of work are lengthened to an average of nine or ten. These data chiefly concern woodcutters. A carter's day is usually longer, carters having to give much time to the care of their horses and means of transport. Special circumstances often make the length of their working days irregular. It appears that they work on Sundays only exceptionally, usually on the execution of repairs or on other tasks enabling the normal course of the weeks' activity. Work on forest holdings is almost invariably piece-work and is paid for according to its quantity, irrespectively of the time spent on it. It follows that to establish statistics as to the worknen's wages and earnings is espe- cially difficult and is possible only in a limited degree. To obtain the most certain data possible a certain number of enquiries were however organized, the results obtained being used to check each other, mutually. Thus on the one hand information as to the normal daily wages of carters, woocutters and other workmen were collected from the authorities and from competent persons in the various districts, and on the other hand the local investigators calculated the average amount earned by a day's work in the places they visited. Finally with respect to a certain number of these places the real gross and net earnings of the workmen were established from wages-lists supplied by the employers. From the chief results of the enquiries the fol- lowing averages can be deduced. They do not however show the notable variations in wages according to districts and to individual holdings, or their variations among the different workmen in one place. 8-31 7-51 6.84 8.78 6.32 6.78 7.26 9.33 IO-63 7-21 8.16 6.86 7.27 8.40 (7.73) 10.58 7.o6 9.78 6.56 7.50 8.64 CONDITIONS OP IvIFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 87 Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Gene- ment ment ment ment ment ment ment ral of of of of of of of Ave- Varm- Koppar- Gavle- Vaster- Jamt- Vaster- Norr- rage land berg borg norrland land botteu botten Carters (horse and mau) Average daily wage accor- ding to: Data ftirnished by comiuiuie 06.94 » » » local enquiry 7.56 » » » wages-list (8.69) Woodcutters Average daily wage accor- ing to : Data furnished by commune 3.05 3.99 3.60 3.38 4.23 3.06 3.32 3.51 » ^ » » localenquiry 3.23 3.91 4.51 3.22 3.62 3.17 3.49 3.68 )) » » wages-list (4.16") (4.06) 4.89 3.15 3.96 3.00 3.62 3.97 (i) All these figures express numbers of crowns, i crown of gold = about is lY^ d at par. From these data it must not be concluded that the earnings discovered by local enquiries and from w^ages-lists for the season 1912-1913, which was as regarded snow a bad season, were generally superior in amount to those which seem from the data stipplied by the communes to be normal. The diffe- rence arises chiefly from the fact that the latter data are of fairly comprehen- sive derivation and thus represent general conditions in the respective de- partments, while the enterprises which have been the object of special en- quiry are chiefly situated in forest areas in which conditions of lodging and provisioning are difficidt, and the price of work therefore reaches a higher level than in agrictiltural areas. Where the forest to be exploited is at a distance, in the interior of the forest areas, workmen can neither live nor eat at home. They must live on the provisions they bring with them or buy on the spot, and these are naturally limited to a small range of articles of diet, easily cooked and kept — chiefl}' bacon, bread, butter, flour, coffee and sugar. With these they pre- pare their own meals. The idea of engaging special assistants, generally women, to cook and do housework has lately arisen, especially in the south- ern parts of the zone of enquiry. The truck system, which obliges work- men in one way or another to buy their provisions from their employer, the foreman or a special dealer, may not now be followed in any of the woods under exploitation. The lack however of a common organization for the procuring of stores and the cooking of food, the waste of foodstuffs, the defective cooking, the increased consumption and the increased prices due to the distance over which transport is necessar}^ — all tliis causes the cost of living to be fairly high while works of forestrj^ are being condcted. The average daity cost is placed at 1.50 crowns for a man and 2.50 crowns for SWEDEN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL a horse, that is 4 crowns for a man and horse. These figures must be remem- bered when the data we have reproduced as to the earnings of forest la- bourers in the various districts and enterprises are estimated. Special attention has been given to housing accomodation because the enquiry was provoked by complaints as to the manner in which the forest labourers were lodged and the frequent defectiveness and inadequacy of the temporary forest huts. The labourers of course endeavour to live at home as much as they can. Failing this possibilit5^ they use any space available in the farms and houses of tenants and in shepherds' cottages, and if these do not suffice more or less temporary huts have to be built for them. Of all the labourers employed on the forest holdings investigated, 37.1 percent, were lodged on farms, 5.6 per cent, in cottages and 57.3 per cent in forest huts. They were most fre- quently lodged in the houses of inhabitants in the departments of Varm- land, Gavleborg and Vasternorrland ; in the other four departments they were mainly accomodated in forest huts. They were lodged in cottages in any large proportion only in the departments of Kopparberg and Jamtland. Labourers lodged in farms and cottages lived far further from their work than those inhabiting the huts, which in a third of the cases were situated at the place of work. Detailed information was obtained as to the accommodation of 1,512 of the 3,103 forest labourers lodged on farms. They shared with 773 per- sons belonging to the farms 447 rooms of which 390 were dwelUng-rooms and kitchens and 57 wash-houses and similar offices. The rooms varied in size but the average floor area was 22.1 square metres (i) and the average cubic area 52.2 cubic metres (2). All the lodgings were provided with windows and fireplaces, generally an open fireplace or a kitchen stove. As regarded sleeping accommodation there were generally beds or recesses taking the place of beds, but in ten cases there were not enough beds and the workmen had to sleep on the floor. As regarded the quality of the lodgings 13.3 per cent, of the rooms in dwelling houses were characterized as draughty, 10 per cent, as cold, 1.3 per cent, as damp and 1.5 per cent, as smoky. Of the lodgings in outhouses the following far larger percentages had the same re- spective defects: 36.8, 42.1, 1.8 and 3.5. On an average five persons were lodged in one room which meant much crowding. The average floor area for each person was 5.6 square metres, the average cubic area 13.5 cubic metres.' In the case of only 5.9 per cent of the workmen thus lodged the cubic area enjoyed b}' each was more than 20 cubic metres ; in the case of 32.5 per cent, it was between 10 and 20 cubic metres ; and 61.6 per cent, mtist therefore be considered to have been lodged in extremely overcrowded rooms. The shepherds' cottages are of the same type as the other cottages in their respective districts ; but they are older and have smaller rooms and more primitive arrangements, and above all they are built not for the win- (i) I square metre = 1.196 square yards. (2) I cubic metre = r.308 cubic yards. CONDITIONS OF WFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 89 ter but for summer. In these huts 471 forest labourers were lodged in eight}^ rooms, of seventy five of which we have descriptions. All the huts had windows and generally the}' were heated by open fireplaces. As sleep- ing accomodation there were usually recesses or beds, but in twenty-one rooms there was only a common camping place. Draughts were a subject of complaint in 53.3 per cent, of the rooms, cold in 46.7 per cent., damp in 5.3 per cent and smoke in 2.7 per cent. The percentages are much higher than in the case of the farms. On an average six persons slept in one room which meant that they were ver>' closely packed. Each person en- joyed on an average 3.3 square metres of floor space and 6.9 cubic metres of air .Onh' 0.2 per cent, of all the workmen so lodged enjoyed 20 cubic metres or more of air and 7.5 per cent, from 10 to 20 cubic metres. For the others, that is 92.3 per cent., the allowance of air was less than 10 cubic me- tres a head, and therefore there was incontestable overcrowding. As regards the temporarj^ forest huts they are of many types determined by the various needs of forest labour and local custom. Beliind these lo- cal variations several principal types can be discerned. The eldpall or fire hut is a wooden hut with a roof sloping to a central pitch wliich has in the middle of its room an open hearth {eldf>all), a sort of rectangular box made of tree-trunks and furnished with sand and earth, on either side of which are common camping places. The chimney-hut is a charcoalburner's hut for from two to four men and has long, sloping walls, covered with earth or other substance, a stone or brick chimney at one end, and one or two camp- ing places beside the walls ; or in some cases it has straight walls, and a big fireplace against one wall or in a corner, which therefore draws better than the fireplaces of fire huts. Of the 521 forest huts inhabited when the local enquiries were made 52.2 per cent, were fire-huts and 47.8 per cent, chim- ney-huts. Of the 4,821 labourers lodged in huts 67.8 per cent, and 32.2 per cent., respectivel}^ dwelt, in huts of the two types, the greater percen- tage inhabiting the fire huts because each of these housed on an average twelve persons, while the average chimne^'-hut, which was onlj^ half as large, housed only half as many. Such temporary dwellings as the forest huts, intended to be used only for a short time, were usuall}' more or less good or bad according to the period at which they were built. Three hundred and three or 58.2 per cent, of them were old, dating from the time of earlier tree-fellings, and had hardly been brought into a habitable state, while 218 or 41.8 per cent, had been built for the tree-felling of the current year. It is noteworthy that only 26.1 per cent, of these new huts had been built in summer — 73.9 per cent, in winter — , although if building be begun after the soil is frozen it is almost impossible to make warm dwelhngs wliich are not draughty. The building of forest huts in winter is generally, espe- cially in the northern departments, not undertaken by an owner on his own soil ; but follows on the annual sales of standing timber by the State at the end of the autumn. Complaints on this subject have not been barren of results ; and steps have recently been taken to time the sales so that they al- go SWEDEN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL low the preliminaty work necessary to the exploitation of forests to be un- dertaken in the propitious season. Half the new huts had been built bj^ the owners of the forests or the trees; half by the workmen themselves, vidth or without compensation. Huts built b}^ emplo3'ers are generally very superior to those which the labourers have been able to make for themselves. A mistaken economy has caused the latter to be constructed as cheaply and quickly as possible, regardless of considerations of hygiene. A fire-hut is said usually to cost lOO crowns in addition to the wood used for it, and the Httle chimney-huts of the charcoalburners' type only half as much. The cost of the larger and better equipped huts is sometimes two or three hundred crowns or even more. Most of the huts examined were built of dead and dry pinewood, but green wood had been used to build quite a third of them, either wholly or partially. The roofs were made of split trunks or boards , a layer of mud or other substance being inserted to conser^-e the heat, and the whole being in most cases crowned bj^ a sloping roof, off which the water ran, made of split trunks, boards, shingles, tarred cardboard, birch bark or si- milar material. The floor was generall}^ of beaten mud, only about a fifth of the huts, and those generalty chimney-huts, having wood floors. A third of the huts had no window, the others a sort of skyhght a few inches square. We have alread mentioned the fireplaces. As sleeping accommodation three fourths of the huts had common camping places while in the others there were beds or box-beds. As regards the general conclusions made by the local investigators as to the huts they examined, the fire-huts, with their central fireplaces, their large outlets for smoke and other openings, were found to be more defective than the more compact chimney- huts. Of huts of the former type 62.1 per cent, were called draughty, 47.1 percent, cold, 39.7 per cent, damp and 54.8 per cent, smoky ; while among huts of the latter tj^pe these percentages were, respectively, 37.8, 25.7, 25.3 and 28.9. The ground area of one of these forest huts is on an average that of one inhabited room — 22.9 square metres ; but since the roof is lower the cubic area is proportionatelv small, averaging 42.9 cubic metres. vSince most of the forest huts were built and equipped exactly to meet determined needs the numberof their inhabitants is less variable but also much larger than that of the farm lodgings. If all the huts be taken together the ave- rage ground area for one person is found to be 2.8 square metres, the cubic area 5.4 cubic metres. The average ground area for one person is 2.8 square metres in the fire-huts, considered separately, 3.1 square metres in the chimney-huts, while the average cubic area is 5 cubic metres in the fire-hvits and 5.8 cubic metres in the chimney-huts, overcrowding being thus most acute in the fire-huts. In huts of both kinds the space allotted to one person is ver>' inferior to the minimum generally considered hy- gienically necessary. However exigencies in the matter of cubic area can and shotdd be different and considerably less when there is question not of closed rooms but of temporaiy and scattered dwellings, having many di- CONDITIONS OF I,IFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 9I rect outlets to the open air. Yet even if the huts be judged as temporary lodgings and with due regard to the special conditions of forest life, a large number of those at present existing must be held to be decidedly inadequate and a larger number to be extremely overcrowded. § 2. Timber floating. When in spring the workmen employed on the winter tree-felling are distributed over different branches of labour, about a tenth of their number seize the opportunity for work offered by timber-floating, which industry is generally managed in this country, technically and economically, not by the private owners of woods but by timber floating societies formed accord- ing to certain rules. The work is one which needs much strength and endu- rance, and it is therefore the young foresters who become floaters. Conse- quently a relatively large number of the floaters belong to the class of la- bourers ; while in the class of forester landowners and leaseholders not the heads of families but their sons and other relatives, who are not absolutely needed for agriculture in the floating season, engage on the work. The conditions of timber-floating are characterized, like those of forest exploitation, by the independence and respousibiht}^ of the labourers, or rather of the working gangs, as a consequence of the small number of work- men and the scattered and changing places of work. These circumstances determine the character of the labour contracts customary in the case of timber floating. They are usually contracts for piece-work concluded with a land-owning cultivator or a leaseholder living near the stream of water, or with some other person accustomed to the local timber-floating. The con- tractor undertakes to ensure the floating of the wood in a certain district, he employs his servants and neighbours or engages additional labour for the purpose. These contracts are also concluded with gangs of a greater or less number of workmen who assume collective responsibihty for the work which they do under the direction of a foreman chosen by themselves. On the streams and the affluents the work generally lasts about four weeks, from the middle or end of May to St. John's day. On the large rivers the season is longer, but it is by no means the same along the whole course of a river : in the lower reaches the larger quantity of floated timber leng- thens it, so that near the mouth, especially near the barriers where sorting takes places, it often lasts throughout the summer. An average working day lasts 12.4 hours on the smaller streams, 11. 7 hours on the large rivers ; but these averages are highly abstract for the work is most irregular. Some- times the floaters merely supervise; sometimes even, for days together, they are quite idle; but at other times their working capacity is taxed to its utmost physical limits, on occasion for several days and nights on end. Although timber-floating is mainly piece-work the wages and earnings of those engaged on it are far less easy to discover than the earnings of the other forest labourers. The regular average daily wages of timber-floaters in the different departments appear from the following table : 92 SWEDEN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Timber Floating on Tributaries •. . . Chief rivers Average Daily Wages in Croipm;. Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- Depart- ment ment ment ment ment meat merit General of of of of of of of Varm- Koppar- Giivle- Vaster- Jamt- Vaster- Norr- Average land berg borg norrland land botteu botten 2.99 3-83 371 4-54 402 4.37 4.63 4.14 3.16 4.00 3.78 4.00 4.30 3.72 4.17 3.94 Food is provided and prepared during the timber-floating season as dur- ing the winter forestry season, certain modifications arising naturall}' out of the difference of conditions, place and time of year. The question of lodgings during the spring timber-floating on the streams and their affluents presents the greatest difficulties. Especially in the northern part of the zone of enquiry atmospheric conditions are still severe, the tem- perature is near zero (Fahrenheit) and there are even falls of snow, and dwell- ing houses are rare in these districts. Often the men are obliged to pass their hours of rest in the open air beside a fire, beneath a temporary roof or a boat turned upside down or with nothing to shelter them against the rain except a reindeerskin, a bed of pine branches or something else of the sort. When timber-floating reaches the chief rivers there is a notable improvement in the conditions in which labourers are lodged. As we have already said a large umber of them live at home, but even the others find good lodgings, the custom being to travel with the floated timber until some farm is found. Where the floating routes pass through sparsely populated forest regions the timber floating societies have, especially of late years, spent much trouble and money in establishing the lodging accommodation which is as necessary to the profit of the enterprise as the workmen themselves. Generally the different types of forest huts have been taken as models ; but as the floaters' huts are intended for more permanent annual use than the foresters' huts they are general^ built more solidly, with higher roofs and larger windows. § 3. Charcoal Burning. As well as the exploitation of forests and timber-floating, charcoal- burning is from the economic and social point of view one of the most im- portant forest industries. The report deals however only in passing with that production of charcoal which has for long been one of the most import- ant elements in intensive forest exploitation in the factory regions. It is more closely concerned with the charcoal-burning in forests which large- ly conforms to the system of extensive forest economy still followed in the north of vSweden. This forest industry aims at utilizing the tree-tops and other remains after the trunks have been cut up, and above all the large CONDITIONS OF T^IFE AND WORK AMONG THE FORESTS 93 quantity of dead trees, standing or fallen, which cover large areas in the fo- rests of Norrland. The employer in the case of charcoal-burning of this type in the forests is generally a firm owning a sawmill, a charcoal company or some indivi- dual — a cultivator landowner, a leaseholder or a rural tradesman who trades in charcoal to a greater or less extent. In certain districts, especially in Upper Norrland, charcoal production is undertaken as a domestic industry by labourers and small cultivators who buy dead wood and other waste in the State forests, cut it up, burn it, and sell the charcoal to traders or to ironworks directly. Small cultivators as well as landless workmen take part in the char- coal-burning in the forests. The proportion in which the different social groups are represented in the industr3' appears from the following figures : of 151 workmen employed in ten charcoal-burning yards which were the object of an especial enquiry, sixty-seven belonged to the landowners' class, eight to that of the leaseholders, seventy-six to that of the labourers. The chief group of labourers employed on charcoal-burning is that of the charcoal-burners , each of whom usually contracts to manufacture a fixed quantity of charcoal for a fixed payment. Where charcoal is manufactured in the forests by a more or less primitive method the charcoal-burners cut the wood for themselves and with their own or with hired horses transport it to the stacks, whence they also transport the charcoal, when it is ready, to the loading places. Where the technique of charcoal-burning is more ad- vanced the charcoal burners generally engage special carters, woodcutters and other workmen whom they pay themselves and who should be consid- ered as being in some degree their assistants. The charcoal-burning season ordinarily lasts about six months in the forests of Norrland. It was sufficiently difficult to obtain precise informa- tion as to the length of the working day, but as far as cutting and transport- ing the wood, setting up the stacks and transporting the charcoal are con- cerned, the work generally coincides with that of exploiting the forests as we have described it. When however charcoal burning is in progress the work is more irregular, for at certain times it is necessary to watch the stacks night and day. On these occasions Sunday work is inevitable, but it is always exceptional. As regards pay, the workmen employed on charcoal-burning generally earn from three to four crowns a day, approximately, and the carters about twice as much for the work of a man and his horse. On the whole charcoal- burning in the forests seems to be a little less profitable to the workmen than tree-felling, especially where natural conditions are not very favourable, and where the industry' is relatively new and the population not very fa- miliar with the process of making charcoal.- The work is however sufficient- ly sought after ; a circumstance explained by the fact that for reasons of transport it is limited to the neighbourhood of means of communication, namely the district within one or two Swedish miles of a railway station, and the workmen usually live at home or in the vicinity and are employed on agricultural labour at certain times of the year. (c) Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases. 1, i,K Service de Protection contre le3 maladies des plantes ex les INSECTES nuisibles daxs les Diver3 PAYS (The Present Organization of the Services for the Control of Plant Diseases and Insect Pests in the Different Countries). (1914, 350 page=;, 4to) Frs. 4.00 a. PRODncnoN et consomm-^tion des Engrais Chimiqctes da.vs le mo:4db (Production and Consumption of Chemical Manures in the World). (Second Edii-ion, 1914, 162 pages, 5 diagrams, 2 maps, i6mo) » 3.50 3. I,A lotte contre les sadterelles DAN3 LES DIVERS p.\YS(The Campaign against L,ocusts in Various Regions) (igi6, 188 pages, i6mo) » 3.50 (d) Publications of the Bureau of Economic and Social Intelligence. 1. I,'ACTIVIT6 DE L'INSTITDT INTERXATIONAL D'AGRICULTURE DANS LE Do- MAINE DE LA COOPERATION, DE L'ASSORANCE ET DU Cr6DIT AGRICOLES (The Work of the International Institute of Agriculture in the Field of Agricultural Co-operation, Insurance and Credit). (In French, German and Italian). (1912, 34 pages, i6mo) • 0.50 2. MONOGRAPHS ON AGRICULTURAL CO-OPERATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES, Vol. I. (1911, 451 pages, i6mo). (In English and French) • 3.50 Do Vol. II. (1915, 213 pages i6mo). (In English and French) ... • 3.50 3. An Outline of thk European Cooperative Credit Systems (Second Edition, 1913, 72 pages, i6mo) 0.50 4. I, 'Organisation de la statistique de la cooperation agricole d.^jis QUELQUES p.\YS (The Organization of Ihe Statistics of Agricultural Co- operation in Certain Countries). (1911, 163 pages, Svo) 1.50 5. I<'ASSURANCE-GRfeLE DANS QUELQUES PAYS ET SES PROBLEMES (lUaUranCe against Hail in Some Countries and its Problems). (1911, no pages, Svo) . . » 1.50 6. AGRICULTURAL CREDIT AND CO-OPERATION IN ITALY: SHORT GUIDE T( RURAL Co-operation in Italy (in English, 35 pages and in Italian 34 pages, i6mo) • 0.25 («) Other publications, I flNSTiTUT International d'Agriculture, son organisation, son activitb, SES rEsultats (The International Institute of Agriculture, its Organization, Activity, and Results). (1914, 31 pages, in English, French and Italian; illustr.) Frs. i — 2 . Louis-Dop : Le Present et l'Avenir de l'Institut International d'Agriculture (Conference) (Present and Future of the International Institute of Agriculture) (Address). (1912, 60 pages, i6mo) • i — 3 , Santiago Aldonate : El Instituto Internacional de AgriCUltura y SU IMPORTANCIA PARA LA AmErICA I,ATINA, EN ESPECIAL PARA CHILE (Con- ferencia) (The International Institute of Agriculture and its Importance for Latin America, especially for Chik). (1913, 30 pages, i6mo) (Address). ... • i — II. Publications not for Sale. I. CONFERENCE INTERNATIONALE DE I905 POUR LA CREATIO.N D'UN INSTITUT 1NTK«NAH0NAL d'Agriculture (International Conference of 1905 for the Foundation of aa Inter- national Institute of Agriculture), (1905, 254 pages, 4to). 3. ACTES DES AssemblEes GEnEr.ales des annEes 1908, 1909, 1911, 1913 (Proceedings of the General Assemblies of 1908, 1909, 1911 and 1913). (Four volimies, Svo., one i6mo). 1. ProcEs-verbaux du ComiiE Permanent des annEes 1908, 1909, 1910, 19x1, 1912, 1913 (Proct^s-verbaux of the Permanent Committee, 1908, 1909, i 10, 19x1. 1912, 1913, 1914 and 19 1 5). (Five volumes, Svo., and two i6mo). i. Rapports et Etudes du Bureau de la St.\tistique GEnErale (Reports and Studies of the Bureau of General Statistics). (1911, 260 pages, Svo). 5. The Science and Practk^e of Farming during xgxo in Great Britain. (646 pages, i6mo). 6. Etude sur les recense-ments de la population agricole, les salaires de la main* d'ceuvre rurale et les courants d'Emigr\tion dans les dippErents Etats (Study on the Census Returns of the Agricultural Population, the Wages of Rural Labour, and the Currents of Emigration in the Several Countries). (igi2, xjo pages, Svo). NOTE, (i) All subscriptions and remittances for the Institute's publications should be made either directly to the International Institute of Agriculture, Rome, or to the principal booksellers. For Great Britain and Ireland, subscriptions to the Bulletins i, 2, 3 and remittances foi the Year Books are also received at the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries, 4 Whitehall Place, London, S W. (2) The prices quoted include packing and carriage. All our publications are despatched on receipt of postal order or international rci>ly coupons. (3) Despatch is made with every c.ire and punctuality, but unregistered volumes travel at consignee's risk. (4) To avoid miscarriage, for which the Institute does not bold itself responsible, an addi- tional amount of 25 centimes for registration should be sent with each order. (5) in case of change of address, the subscriber is requesiedto notify the Publishing Bureau of the Institute, forwarding address label. ^^A INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE Bureau of Economic and Soclai, Intei,wgence INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (MONTHLY BULLETIN OF ECONOMIC AND SOCL\L INTELLIGENCE) VOLUME LXXVIII. 8th. YEAR: NUMBER 6 JUNE, 1917. ROME PRINTrNG OFFICE OF THE INSTITUTE I9I7 Publications of the International Institute of Agriculture. i8 i8 36 I. Publications for Salei Annus] A. — MONTHLY OR WEEKLY PUBLICATIONS* •nb^crlptioa 1. International Crop Report and Agricultur-vl Statistics {Bulletin — 0/ Agricultural and Commercial Statistics), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian, i6mo Frs. 6 2. International Review of the Science and Practice op AGRicuLTaRB {Monthly Bulletin of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian. (Bach number consists of about 180 pages, i6mo) 3. International Review of Agricultural Economics {Monthly Bulletin of Economic and Social Intelligence), published monthly in English, French, German, Spanish and Italian. (Each number consists of about 150 pages, i6mo) Subscription to all three Bulletins B. — HALF-YEARLY PUBLICATIONS. 1. Statistical Notes on Cereals. Studies on yield, trade, consumption aud prices, with rates of ocean freight , Fra, 2. The International Movement of Fertilisers and Chemical Products useful to Agriculture • C. — YEAR BOOKS. 1. Amnuaire Inters ational de Statistique Agricole pous 19 10 (International Year Book of Agricultural Statistics, 1910). (i9i2,XI,VIIl-f-337 pages, i6mo) Do. Vol. II, Years 1911-1912. (1914, XXXIV + 624 pp. i6mo) .... Do. Vol. Ill, Years 1913-1914. (191 5, XI,IV + 788 pp. i6mo) , . . 2. Annuaire International de I 4. Notes sur les Statistiques du Commerce ext6rieur dans les dippS- RENT3 Pays: Publications Statistiques, Territoires, Sortes de Commerce, Provenances et Destinations des Marchandises (Notes on the Statistics erf Foreign Trade in the Different Countries : Statistical Publications, Territory, Kinds of Trade, Sotuce and Destination of Goods). (1914, 96 pages, i6mo) . » 5. 1,A RfePARTixiON Agricole des Territoires des dipf6rbnts Pays (Areai under Crops in the Different Countries). (1914, 310 pages, i6mo) .... • (3) Other publications. Dmberto Ricci : I,E3 Bases tedSoriques de la Statistique Agricolb in- ternationalb (Theoretical Bases of International Agricultural Statistics), (19141 314 pages, i6mol > Single number 0,60 1,50 i,!0 3 3 5 10 ' 10 10 ' 10 10- 3 — 0.30 5 — INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE Bureau of Economic and Sociai, Inteli.igence INTERNATIONAL REVIEW OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS (MONTHLY BULLETIN OF ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL INTELLIGENCE) VOLUME LXXVIII. 8th. YEAR: NUMBER 6 JUNE, 1917. ROME printing office of the institute 19x7 CONTENTS PART I : CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Spain. The First Co-operative Cheese Factory Page § I. Antecedents, page i. — § 2. The working of the Co-operative Society, page 2. — §3. Results obtained, page 4. Italy. The Development of the Co-operative Movement in Italy according to Recent Statistical D.ata as to the " L,eg.\ Nazion.ale delle Cooper.\tive " . . Pa^e '§ I . The Number of Co-operative Societies in the Kingdom and their Geographical Distribution, page 7. — § 2. The Number of Members, page 9. — § 3. The Finan- cial Biisis and the Business of the Societies, page 10. — § 4. Profits and I^ since they would thus be idle for nine months of the year. The problem is solved by appoint- ing as master cheesemaker one of the shepherds in the employ of the mem- bers and others as assistant cheesemakers, the chosen men always having special skill in the trade. The factory pa^-s these employees during the cheesemaking season, providing substitutes to do their ordinary work as. shepherds. THE FIRST CO-OPERATIVE CHEESE FACTORY The costs of installation are distributed in equal shares among the mem- bers. Ten per cent, of their amount is annually deducted from the societj- 's profits and distributed among the members as interest and redemption quota on the capital of installation. The remaining profits are distributed among them in proportion to the quantity of milk each of them has supplied during the cheesemaking season. The following are the only figures we have as to the quantities of milk supplied by the members, and refer to 1914. No. of days during which they supplied milk Quantity of milk in kilogrammes (i) Members Total Daily average Daily maximum Daily minimum No. I No. 2 67 60 88 87 76 23,709 12,846 15,003 7,338 6,168 334 214 170 8.4 81 526 262 259 114 105 204 lOI No. 3 . No. 4 No. 5 49 32 31 Total . . . 88 65,064 739 1,190 49 (i) I kilogramme = 2.2 lbs. The members are obliged to deliver perfectly strained milk and to bring it to the factory in vessels of tinned iron, quite full and hermetically sealed. In order to prevent the adulteration of the milk by the addition of water or other substances it is analysed on its arrival at the factory. For its transport the members have adopted a system of special carts furnished with awTiings and so made that the vessels are exposed neither to the sun nor to rain. For the installation of the factory the premises formerly used for cheese- making by a member were chosen and were suitably transformed and en- larged. The factory now occupies a fine two-storied building covering an area of 300 square metres (2). On the ground floor are the reception room, the depot, two large rooms used as warehouses, two others used as factories, one for the boiler and stove, and the dwellings of the cheesemakers. On the upper stor^^ there are warehouses in which as many as 5,000 cheeses can be stored and which have all the conditions taught b}^ science and expe- rience to be necessary to the preservation of manchego cheese. The disposition of the cheeses, the accommodation, the ventilation and the economy'' realized make these premises a true model for establishments of their kind. {2) I square metre -= 1.196 siiuure yards. SPAIN - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION § 3. Results obtained. The following are some data which resume the activity of the co-opera- tive society during the three years which have elapsed since its foundation. No. of days Quantity Year for which of milk treated Profits realized the season lasjed — — — kilogrammes pesetas (i) 1914 88 65,064 22,585, 1915 87 67,132 24,751 T916 81 51.262 23,300 These figures need some explanation. If the cheesemaking industry be always highly subject to variation it is so especially when the animals furnishing the milk which is its material are not stalled, for milk production is then intimately connected with the extent and quality of the pastures on which they graze. The difference in the quantity of milk treated from one to another of the three years considered should not cause surprise. Cheese is made in Infantes in the spring, and it should be remembered that in 1915 there was an early and productive spring, whereas that of 1916 was late and little productive. The difference in the prices realized is similarly explained, being partly due to the varying price of the cheese from one year to another. The co-operative society declares that the fact that the business had entered into a regular course of working contributed to the increase in individual returns obta^ined in 1916. A fact which must at first sight cause surprise is that the manufactur- ing season of the Queseria Manchega should last only from eighty-one to eighty-eight days. This is due to local conditions of vegetation and to the difficulty of changing local customs in the matter of sheep farming. In order to lengthen the season and make a larger quantity of cheese it would be necessary to sacrifice the lambs soon after their birth and give fresh and abundant food to the ewes in order that they might yield milk for as long as possible. This is at present impossible in this district where the winter is long and unproductive and the spring very productive, so that the farmers keep the lambs in order to use the abundant pasturage. It is therefore only when the lambs can live without their mothers, that is in spring, that the ewes are milked for the purpose of cheesemaking, the practice being continued until the great heat of July begins to burn the fields. The position could certainly be modified by the intensive culti- vation of forage plants and the stalling of the sheep, but this presupposes a complete change in the local system of sheep farming, which could be accomplished only after long study on the part of the farmers. (1)1 peseta = i> ^/^ d. at par. THE FIRST CO-OPERATIVE CHEESE FACTORY It is calculated that the flocks belonging to members of the Queseria Manchega comprise 6,000 ewes. As regards their yield it should be noted that, as is seen by the table referring to the season of 1914, the members do not all contribute milk on even,'' day for which the factory works. It may be said, to sum up, that the Queseria Manchego has attained to extremely satisfactor}' results. Since a first attempt at co-operative manufacture is in question, and since there is an increasing demand for its products owing to their superiority over others of the same kind, we may hope that farmers in other parts of Spain will follow the example which has been set them, to their own advantage, that of the industry and that of stock farming. Already we can cite two other co-operative societies, founded under the auspices of the Asociacion general de Ganadoros for the exploitation of dairy industries. They are the Cooperativa Lacianiega for buttermaking at Villabliuo in Leon, and the Lecheria cooperativa established at Saragossa for the sale of milk bv the local Casa de Ganaderos. ITALY. THE DEVElvOPMENT OF THE CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT IN ITALY ACCORDING TO RECENT STATISTICAL DATA AS TO THE " LEGA NAZIONALE DELLE COOPERATIVE ". SOURCE : Annuakio statistico 1 91 6 DEi.LE societA cooperative esistenti in Italia, escluse quelle CHE HANNO PER scopo PRiNCiPALE l'esercizio DEL CREDiTO (Statistical Yearbook 191 6 of Co-operative Societies in Italy, exclusive of such as have the affording of Credit as their C^j'e/ .4 tw). lyCga Naziouale delle Cooperative Italiane (A^ahonfli League of Italian Co-op- erative Socielies) (Milan). Como, Tipografia Cooperati\'a Comense « A. Barin, 191 7. The Milanese National League of Co-operative Societies had already in 1903 published the first collection to appear in Italy of general statistics as to these societies. It had the support of the Ministry of Agriculture, Industry and Commerce and the assistance of another Milanese society, the Societa Umanitaria ; and the resultant collection was the Statistica delle Societa cooperative italiane esistenti nel 1902 (i). Recently the league has published a Statistical Yearbook of Co-operative Societies for 1916, excluding credit societies. The object of this publication is to " place in relief the importance of the Italian co-operative movement, paying spe- cial attention to those forms of co-operation which are recruited from the humblest classes ". The book has 1500 pages and is the result of long and intensified labour in collecting and elaborating data. It is indubi- tably the most complete work of its kind which has yet appeared in Italy (2). It comprises : a) a list of all the existing co-operative societies ; h) a (i) This collection contained three statistical tables and an appendix. Table I. comprised 2199 societies and gave data regarding them having reference to 31 December 1901 and distri- buted in four groups (consumption, production and labour, credit, various) and according to the district in which they were situated. Of these societies 1714 comprised 367,450 members and owned a total capital of 74,121,046 liras. In Table II 2199 of the same societies reap- peared, distributed in twelve classes according to their nature and the object of their social enterprise. Table III. gave 322 co-operative societies of Italians outside Italy. In an appen- dix there was a list of 335 co-operative societies existing in 1902, the data as to which arrived only after the two first talile had been drawn up and printed. There followed the enumeration of eighteen institutions of propaganda and aid, such as the Lega nazionale and the district, provincial and local federations, and numerous tables. (2) Other publications of the same kind have been printed bj' the offices of the Direzione generate del Credito e delta Prevtdenza at the Ministry of Agriculture , Industry and Commerce. One of these, which appeared in 1908, is a mere list, showmg the date at which the co-operative societies were formed and giving information as to their paid-up capital. Another which was more complete appeared in 1910, and the j^earbook under review refers to this m making the comparisons by which it places in relief the progress of the movement from igiotoigi.?. THE DEVEI.OPMENT OF THE CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT collection of tables giving information as to the development of most of the co-operative societies in the sixty-nine provinces of the kingdom, as regards each form of co-operation ; c) a collection of tables resuming the situation for each province and district and thus giving a complete pic- ture of the development to which this organization has attained in Italy ; d) as an appendix a list of alj co-operative societies entered in the registers of the existing prefectorates, fererations and consortia. We will here reproduce the principal data contained in this yearbook. § I. The number of co-operative societies in the kingdom AND THEIR GEOGRAPHICAI, DISTRIBUTION. It should first be stated that the league's researches concerned the following forms of co-operation : a) consumers' societies ; b) producers' and labour societies ; c) societies for the construction of popular dwellings ; d) agricultural societies ; e) insurance societies. In the case of the first four of these the aim was the discovery of the following data : i) date of formation ; 2) number of members ; 3) capital shares, subscribed or paid-up ; 4) amount of the various funds, reserve and other ; 5) amount of business ; 6) profits ; 7) losses. Research of this kind was omitted in the case of the insurance societies owing to the great variety of their working. There were, in 1915, 7,429 co-operative societies, as against 5,064 in 1910. They were distributed as follows : 1915 19 10 Difference Co-operative consumption production and labour building " agriculture insurance. Total . . . 7429 5064 + 2365 The co-operative societies of production and labour occur in the year- book in sixteen sections, according to their objects, namely : i) bakehouses, mills and slaughterhouses ; 2) miners, stoneworkers and cementers ; 3) wood and leather ; 4) ceramics and glass ; 5) fishermen ; 6) copyists and printers ; 7) mechanics and metallurgists ; 8) chemical industries, 9) electrical in- dustries ; 10) clothing and textile industries ; 11) painters and decorators ; 12) journeymen, wheelwrights and navvies; 13) carters, waggoners; 14) porters' work ; 15) variotis ; 16) mixed. The agricultural societies are divided into three section : i) agricul- ture and culture of special crops ; 2) viticulture and the vintners' industry ; 3) dairy farming and cheesemaking. The figures given show that the number of co-operative societies in- creased by 2365 between 1910 and 1915. If insurance societies, which di- 2408 1756 + 652 3022 1879 + 1143 752 379 + 373 II42 925 + 217 105 125 — 20 ITALY - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION minished by twenty (i6 per cent.), be excluded, those of every other form are seen to have increased largely — the building societies by 98.4 per cent ; those of production and labour by 60.8 per cent. ; those of consumption by 37-1 per cent. ; and the agricultural societies by 23.4 per cent. If the co-operative societies be distributed geographically the following comparison between 1915 and 1910 is obtained. Table I. — Local Distribution of co-operative societies. Co-operative societies Consump- tion Aaricultural Production and labour Building Piedmont I^igtiria Lombardy Venetia Emilia and Romagna , Tuscany Marches Umbria Latium Abruzzi and Molise. . Campania Apulia Basilicata Calabria Sicily Sardinia 277 105 704 191 338 358 III 56 28 30 47 40 6 42 63 12 484 143 157 267 105 38 16 32 35 30 2 28 53 6 95 27 224 95 216 42 26 10 65 21 53 64 10 27 145 22 84 22 140 84 214 38 22 6 61 II 55 43 II 20 105 9 151 183 394 322 886 239 78 31 226 12 III 146 14 46 159 24 109 103 298 174 555 131 46 15 184 6 63 85 8 10 82 10 33 70 144 59 133 127 10 7 122 3 18 13 6 2 3 2 75 4 16 3 3 3 We should also note the development of agricultural co-operative so- cieties in Sicily, those of production and labour and of building in Emilia and Romagna, those of consumption in lyombardy, etc. Generally speaking societies are most numerously formed in the districts in which agriculture and industry are most cteveloped. In order to show more clearly the intensity of the co-operative move- ment in the various districts, we reproduce the following table in which the number of societies is considered in relation to the density of population in each district and the number of its communes. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT Table II. — Number of co-operative societies as compared to the population and the comniunes in each district Population in 1915 No. of Com- munes in 1915 Co-operative Societies Classification Districts No. of CO ope- rative societies No. of inhabi- tants for each society No. of Com- munes for each society according to population according to number of communes Piedmont. . . 3,472,958 1,489 620 5,601 2.40 Emilia Emilia I/i^ria . . 1,244,015 305 389 3.189 0.78 Latium Tuscany Lombardy 4.931.485 1,907 1,477 3.338 1.28 Liguria Latium Venetia. . 3.665.536 798 669 5.479 1. 19 Lombardy Liguria Emilia . . 2,764,133 328 1,575 1,755 0.20 Tuscany Apulia Tuscany . 2,756,654 287 77c. 3,580 0.37 Marches Sicily Marches . 1,115,969 254 225 4.964 1. 17 Venetia Marches Umbria. . 703,802 152 104 6,767 1.46 Piedmont Venetia Latium . . 1.361,337 228 447 3.045 0.51 Umbria lyombardy Abruzzi . . 1,459,580 463 68 21,464 6.80 Apulia Umbria Campania. 3,377,824 623 231 14,622 2.70 Sicily Piedmont Apulia . . 2,201,241 241 263 8,369 0.91 Calabria Campania Basilica ta. 481,953 126 36 13.387 3-5° Basilica ta BasUicata Calabria . 1,446,773 415 117 12.365 3-54 Sardinia Calabria Sicily. . . 3.743,447 362 374 10,009 0.96 Campania Sardinia Sardina . 870,077 363 64 13.594 5-67 Abruzzi Abruzzi All Italy . 35.597,784 8,341 7,429 4.791 (I) 1.12 (i) In these calculations the total number of co-operative societies, as given in the list in the yearbook, is taken into account. § 2. The number of members. Of 7,317 co-operative societies of consumption, production and labour, building and agriculture, to which the league addressed itself, only 5,036 or about 70 per cent, supplied the desired data. Moreover the forms were not completely filled up, the number of members being omitted on some, and the amount of business, the capital, the reserve fund, etc. on others. As regards the members we compare in the following table the number of them in the various kinds of co-operative societies in 191 5 a.nd in 1910 : 10 ITAI,Y - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION Table III. — Number of members oj co-operative societies. Statistics Classification 1915 1910 of the No. of societies No. of membets No. of societies co-operative societies in existence to which information refers in existence to which information refers members Consumption .... Production and labour Building Agricultural 2408 3015 751 1 143 1970 1884 471 711 411.358 257.149 91,812 195,766 1764 1871 379 926 1623 1357 315 827 346,474 212,387 49,466 161,115 7317 5036 956,085 4940 4122 769,442 Thus the membership of these co-operative societies increased altogether between 1910 and 1915 by 186,643. ^^ it be remembered that 2,278 societies furnished no data in 1915 and 718 in 1910, and if it be calculated that each society has about 190 members, it is no exaggeration to place the total membership at 1,300,000, giving an increase of 400,000 since 1910. But the increase arises also from an increase in the number of societies, and there- fore we must conclude that there has been no true progress in this sphere. If finally each kind of co-operative society examined be considered separately, it is seen that while the average membership of a consumers' society fell between 1910 and 1915 from 213 to 208, and that of a produc- tion and labour society from 156 to 136, that of a building society rose from 157 to 195 and that of an agricultural society from 195 to 275. § 3. The financial basis and the business OF THE SOCIETIES. The financial basis of the societies appears from the following compa rative figures for 1910 and 191 5 : Paid-up Capital . Reserve & various Funds. 191 5 Co-operative consumers' societies . Iv. production and labour societies .... " " building (i) societies. agricultural societies " 31,617,205.72 ly. 23,868,709 3,255.547-3i 32,257,311.45 21,687,867.42 31,481,004 43,109,237 15,687,199 Total L. 118,817,841.90 Iv. 114,146,149 (i) The apparent diminution in the assets and reserves of the building societies should be ascribed to the fact that i!i the yearbook under review the special autonomous institutions for popular dwellings, of which many were formed after 1908, were by an error omitted. THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE CO-OPERATIVE MOVEMENT II Taken together the co-operative societies of various kinds possess property, paid-up capital and reserves of the average value of 23,593.69 liras and individual members are interested to the extent of 124.28 liras each. The average property of a consumers' co-operative society amounts to 16,049.49 liras, that is 76.86 liras a member; that of a production and labour society to 17,651.12 liras or 129.32 liras a member. The economic resources of other forms of co-operation are more important, as regards the average both for a member and for a society. This is easily explain- ed. We have but to remember that by the law of 1908 as to popular dwellings the building societies were exempted from the provisions of the commercial code as to series of shares, which cannot be of more than 100 liras. In the case of agricultural societies it should be borne in mind that they include the large organizations for the distribution of fertilizers and seeds and those which, like the cheese factories and the collective cellars, treat products. The turnover of more than 5,000 co-operative societies in 1915 was 648,248,972.82 liras, distributed as follows : co-operative agricultural societies . . " liras 211,514,782.82 production and labour societies ... " 163,732,001.14 consumers'societies " 156,841,214.87 building societies " 116,160,973.99 These figures would give for every consumers' co-operative society an average turnover of 79,614.82 liras. If the fact be recollected that only 1,970 out of 2,408 co-operative societies of this kind supplied information on this point it may be calculated, even if an average turnover of no more than 50,000 liras a year be ascribed to societies which did not respond, that the total annual value of the sales made by consumers' co-operative socie- ties was 180,000,000 liras. A comparison with the average turnover of each consumers' co-op- erative society, as shown by the statistics of 1902, reveals an increase of 11,170.58 liras, namely, one from 68,444.34 liras to 79,614.82 liras. In the case of the production and labour societies this increase is much more marked, being one of 51,495.29 liras which raised the amount from 35,192.21 liras in 1902 to 86,588.10 liras in 1915. This is explained 63- the fact that all Italian laws facilitating the participation of societies of this kind in public auctions are posterior to 1902, as appears in an article on this subject which we published in our issue for November 1914. § 4. Profits and losses. We will end our short examination of the figures given in the yearbook by showing the profits and losses resulting from these co-operative busi- nesses. The total profits amounted to 11,236,722.18 liras and the total losses to 1,237,985.38 liras : and the net profits were therefore 9,998,736.80 12 ITAI,Y - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION liras. Profits and losses were distributed as follows among the various groups of societies: Co-operative agricultural societies : Profits I^iras 1,919,178.22 Losses " 208,640.14 Net profits . . . Iviras 1.680.538.08 Co-operative production and labour societies : Profits Iviras 4,625,237.83 Ivosses " 484,105.42 Net profits . . . Liras 4,141,132.41 Co-operative consumers' societies : Profits Iviras 3,471,956.51 Losses. . - '' 368,854.30 Net profits . . . Liras 3,103,102.21 Co-operative huilding societies '. Profits Liras 1,220,349.62 Losses " 146,385.52 Net profits . . . Liras 1,073,964.10 These figures are the best assurance of the soundness of Italian co- operative enterprise. SWITZERLAND. THE PEASANTS' UNION AND PEASANTS' SECRETARIAT IN 1916. SOURCE : DiX-NEUVIEME RARFORT ANNUEL DU COMITE DIRECTEUR DE ly' UNION SUISSE DES PAYSANS ET DU Secretariat des Paysans Suisses, 1916 (Nineteenth Annual Report of the Managing Committee of the Swiss Union of Peasants and the Secretariat of Swiss Peasants, 1916). Brougg, Secretariat of Swiss Peasants, 1917, 95 pages. The nineteenth annual report of the managing committee of the Swiss Union of Peasants and the Secretariat of Swiss Peasants treats of the ac- tivity of these two institutions in 1916, shows its results, adducing evidence, and publishes data relative to the finances of the institutions. We will examine this important report and resume its chief parts, as we have done in the case of reports of earlier years. A. — SWISS PEASANTS' UNION. § I. Social position and activity of the union in 1916. In the beginning of 1916 the Swiss Peasants' Union had twenty-eight sections which comprised 197,761 members. During the year one new society adhered to the union and was admitted as forming a new section. This was the Federation des societes de mise en valeiir du lait de la Suisse Centrale (Federation of the Societies for Realizing the Value of the Milk of Central Switzerland). The union thus acquired 6,451 new members. a) Economic Measures for Meeting the Effects of the War. In 1916 the union took economic measures with a view to meeting the effects of the war. They were rendered necessary by the circumstances to which the war gave rise in Switzerland and they greatly preoccupied the managing committee, and more especially the Peasants' Secretariat, as well as the Office of Information as to Prices. As regards the potato supply, the defective potato harvest was a pretext for reproaching the farmers for hoarding seed potatoes for motives of speculation. But the Peasants' Secretariat took its stand on the result of enquiries made by the Office of Information as to Prices, and was able to show that this reproach was unfounded and thus to contribute to calming public opinion. The union undertook to take an inventory of the stocks of pota- 14 SWITZERLAND - CO-DPERATION AXD ASSOCIATION toes, rather however out of consideration for the public than in the hope of securing new supplies for consumption. The union opposed a proposal to requisition potatoes because it was already the agriculturist's interest to sell his whole available supply and requisition might have influenced the potato crops unfavourably. The principal task of the State is to provide as ample a supply of seeds as possible and to persuade those interested to grow potatoes as extensively as possible. The importance of taking in- ventories of the available supply is that it prepares the way for the discharge of this task. The union has been occupied with the reduction of the rate for the ex- traction of meal, the provision of home-grown cereals as fodder, the guaran- teeing of a minimum price for cereals, the utilization of rye for the brewing industry, the prohibition which burdens trade in forage, the price of straw and the supply of straw to the army, the delivery of live stock for butchery to the army, the export of income producing stock and of young pigs, and questions relative to milk and dairy products. The union's action in endeav- ouring to obtain leave for soldiers belonging to the cheesemaking industry has not been unattended with difficulty but has been crowned with success. The union has also been occupied with the question of obtaining payments for hire for requisitioned horses, and that of suppressing such requisition and causing a return to the method of supplying horses voluntarily. Swiss agriculture is represented at the general meeting of the Socieie Suisse de Surveillance Economique (Swiss Society of Economic Superintendence), or S. S. S., by the national counsellor, M. Chuard and by Dr. Laur. These have taken advantage of opportunities for discussing the needs of agriculture, especially where the acquisition of forage is concerned. Most of the fe- derations of agricultural syndicates have adhered to the S. S. S. This affi- liation has given the agricultural syndicates of Romanic Switzerland an opportunity to group themselves unitedly, thus satisfying a long felt want. M. Chuard, member of the union's managing committee, and M. Laur, di- rector of the Swiss Peasants' Secretariat, were the delegates of the Federal Council at the negotiations in Paris with the allied countries as to the vic- tualling of Switzerland. b) Law as to epizooty policies, application of the law as to insurance against sickness and accidents, the customs tariff and other enterprise. In 1 91 5 the proposed revision of the federal law as to the campaign against epizooty, published by the federal council in the message of 15 March 1915, was carefully examined by the union and the secretar5^ Their conclusions on the subject were resumed by the committee and then trans- mitted to the commission of the federal Chambers. These began in 1916 to discuss the proposal, and the desires of the union were partially taken into consideration and in a measure respected. The administrative council of the Caisse nationale Suisse d' assurance en cas d'accidents (Swiss National Fund for Insurance against Accidents) is concerned with the institution of compulsory insurance and prepara- THE PEASANT S UNION AND PEASANTS SECRETARIAT 15 tions for voluntary insurance have not yet been begun. During the discuss- ion as to insurance against accidents the union brought forward proposals as to agriculture which were accepted. It proposed finally that the fores- ters of communes should in particular all be insured. As regards the revision of commercial treaties, of which one with Italy was denounced innnediately before the end of the year, the Peasants' Se- cretariat continued to prepare for the new agreements to be made. The union also undertook much other business as to the export and import of certain merchandise and relative custom duties, the inspection of wines at the frontier, post office savings banks, the agricultural press, aliens, the federal grant for research as to the productiveness of agriculture, and the federal grants to the federation of the agricultural societies of Romanic Switzerland and in aid of vegetable gardening. § 2. Office of information as to prices. From the report which this office presented to the Swiss Peasants' Union it appears that its activity had the following forms : a) The collection of reports from which extracts were made ; b) The publication of a review of the markets ; and the supply of information as to the course of production, the position of the markets and the price of agricvdtural products ; c) The supply of information as to the international market for milk and dairy produce ; d) The collection of material for drawing up reports to be sent to the International Institute of Agriculture at Rome. This office has recently assumed a growing importance which is reflected in all its branches. In 1916 it sent out 11,239 circulars and communica- tions of which 8,725 were in German, 1,823 ^^ French, 309 in Italian and 301 in English. The number of its correspondents has not been diminished in spite of the special circumstances due to the war and the fact that a certain number of them have been called to serve in the army. Correspondents who were obliged definitely to resign have been replaced. 7,183 were in this case. The especial circumstances due to the war obliged the office to devote particular attention to the statistics as to Swiss crops. The office un- dertook the following enquiries : i) An enquiry as to modifications in the area on which cereals and po- tatoes are grown (about 900 correspondents). 2) An enquiry as to the average yield per hectare (i). 3) An enquiry as to the Swiss potato harvest in 1916 (600 correspondents). An enquiry, pursued in 1,643 communes, as to the quantity of fruit which could be sold during the autumn of 1916. ' (i) I hectare = 2.47 acres. l6 SWITZERIAND - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The average edition of each number of the Revue des marches (Review of the Markets) is of 85,471 copies of which 74,406 are in German and 11,065 in French. In 1915 the average edition was of 79,060 copies. The review has been inserted in ten German and two French agricultural journals. In 1916 the oihce had to confine itself to following the course of prices in the interior. The movement of foreign markets has been paralysed by the impositon of maxinuim prices, the prohibition against export, and in general by circumstances due to the war ; and therefore their importance has compared with that of Swiss markets is quite secondary. Nevertheless the abundance of material obliged the editor of the Revue des marches to publish three double numbers in the German edition. The Office of Information as to Prices also sent the following notices to the journals subscribing to the Revue des marches : A communication explaining the provisions as to the price of milk and cheese ; Two comnumications as to the price of milk for consumption ; Two communications as to dairy production ; Eight reports on the market for fruit ; One publication as to the Swiss cereal and potato harvest ; One communication as to the placing of agricultural labour by the Swiss labour offices ; Two reports on the world's cereal harvest in 1916. As in former years the chief conclusions derived from the statistics as to prices, which were drawn up by the office, were placed at the disposal of the Federal Statistical Office which published them in the Swiss Statistical Yearbook. In the beginning of the year a complementary report was drawn up as to the valuation of live stock in view of the war tax, and this report was sent by the Peasants' Secretariat to the Federal Department of Finances. The Office of Information has been occupied by preparations and deliberations with reference to the price of milk and cheese, and has forwarded a large number of pertinent requests. During the autumn of 1915 an enquiry was undertaken in order to discover the increase in the area planted with cereals and potatoes as com- pared with 1914. A new enquiry in June 1916 aimed at discovering the modification of such area since 1915. The office received relevant reports from 850 correspondents in all parts of the country. As compared with 1915 the increase in the cultivated area was one of 9.7 per cent for cereals and 13.5 per cent, for potatoes. As compared with 1914 it was 20.8 per cent, for cereals and 32.2 per cent, for potatoes. An enquiry was also begun as to the average harvest yields per hec- tare, to provide a basis for the annual estimates of the cereal and potato harvests made by the office. For this enquiry' the office made use of for- mer pupils of the schools of agriculture, most of whose societies have pro- mised their co-operation. For the first time this office made the attempt of conducting an en- quiry among producers in order to discover the harvest yield calculated THE PEASANTS UNION AND PEASANTS SECRETARIAT 1 7 on the percentage of the average and on the yield per hectare of the potato harvest in 1916. According to the data as to the percentage of the ave- rage yield the probable total yield was estimated at 5.9 million quintals (i). If however the data as to the yield per hectare be taken as basis the resultant estimate is 6.1 million quintals. The yield has therefore been estimated in round figures at 6 million quintals. The activity of the office also included an enquiry- made in autumn as to the amount of fruit available for sale. The enquiry- was made by com- nmnes and the questions w^ere sent to 1,643 communes in the fruit-growing districts of German and Romanic Switzerland. The answers received numbered, 1,494. The quantities available for sale were as follows : Table apples . 200,000 quintals Cider apples 230,000 Early cider pears ,44,000 Late cider pears 40,000 Prunes 2,700 Nuts 1,100 In the matter of information as to the international market for milk and dairy produce, the quarterly statements were drawn up as previously in spite of difiiculties caused by the war. The following organizations lent their aid : i) Austria : General Union of Agricultural Co-operative vSocieties of Austria seconded by the Imperial and Royal Society of Agriculture. 2) Belgium : International Dairy Federation. 3) Canada and the United States : Various communications. 4) Denmark : Royal Society of Agriculture of Denmark. 5) France : Various local and provincial organizations, individuals. 6) Germany : Various local and provincial organizations, individuals. 7) Great Britain : The Board of Agriculture (by sending publica- tions), various organizations. 8) Holland : General Dairy Union of the Netherlands. 9) Hnmary : Division for the Dairy Industry and Alpine Economy of the Royal Ministry of Agriculture (by sending question-forms and re- ports), seconded by the National Society of Agriculture of Hungary. 16) Italy : National Union of Co-operative Dairies, local associa- tions, individuals. 11) Norway : National Committee of the International Dairy Fe- deration. 12) Sxi'edcn : Secretariat of the Royal Academy of Agriculture. Quarterly reports were sent as usual to correspondents at home and abroad. The average quarterly edition was of 2,525 German and 1,255 French copies, and 120 extracts in German, 50 in French, 220 in ItaHan and 150 in English. (i) I quintal = 220 lbs. SWITZERLAND - CO-OPERATIOX AND ASSOCIATION The ofl&ce sent month by month to the International Institute of Agriculture at Rome its customary reports on the condition of the prin- cipal crops, of silkworm rearing, of foreign trade in cereals, and of beetroot growing and sugar production, and on the provisional and final estimates of the cereal and j)otato harvests, wine production, the tobacco harvest, etc. § 3. Office of valuation. The amount of business entrusted during igi6 to the Office of Valua- tion was so large that it was necessary to engage new experts. Its activity, as determined by its rules, comprised : a) The drawing up of reports on investigations and valuations made at the request of individuals in the case of the repurchase of inheritances, successions, acquisitions of real estate, requests for credit and applications for compensation for damage to crops. As in the previous year the largest number of applications for valuations were made by individuals. b) Investigations and valuations for institutions of credit and the State. c) Investigations and valuations in cases of expropriation. d) Co-operation in legal or official valuations. e) Contributions to scientific research in the matter of agricultural taxation. The value of the real estate valued in 1916 was as follows : Real estate valued according to the income it pro- duced .... 3,266,000 francs » )) » » » its selling value. 1,762,000 » )^ )' )) B )' its value for the maintenance of a family 632,000 « Recourse was also had to the Office of Valuation for information of ever}^ description. Besides its simple communications the office made real studies of the most diverse questions, among them those inherent in the law of succession among peasants, the purchase and sale of real estate, the letting of real estate, due services and the land tax. § 4. The office of information as to insurance against accidents and sickness. This office has had to suppl}^ information as to the foundation of sick- ness funds and in one case to pronounce on projected by-laws which had already been drawn up. The office has been asked for other information, especially on the subject of insurance against risks of civil liability. THE PEASANTS UNION AND PEASANTS SECRETARIAT IQ § 5. The BU11.DING OFFICE. A new institution, which has certainly rendered notable service to Swiss agriculture, was formed last j^ear, namely the Office of Rural Building. This office, formed on the model of those existing in Germany, is occupied not only with farm buildings but also with those necessary to the cheesemaking industry. Its activity has the following forms : i) It gives information by word of mouth. 2) It answers requests for information addressed to the State. 3) It communicates its observations and proposals, following on investigations made on the spot, by writing or by word of month. 4) It makes sketches and plans. 5) It supplies addresses of contractors and those furnishing supplies. 6) It makes specifications. 7) It undertakes the superintendence of building. 8) It verifies building accounts. The new office was opened on i January 1917 and necessary rules and a scale of charges will be drawn up for it. B. — SECRETARIAT OF SWISS PEASANTS. § I. Programme of work. The programme of work laid down by the union for the Secretariat of Swiss Peasants comprised : i) Preparations for the revision of commercial treaties. 2) The question of agricultural labour. 3) Researches as to the income produced by agriculture. 4) Researches by means of double-entry book-keeping. 5) Reorganization of the archives and the library. The work concerned with preparations for the revision of the customs tariff was carried on as far as time allowed. In the matter of rural labour the secretariat published a fourth part of its work on this subject at the end of 1916. It forms the last chapter of the proposals of the secretariat for the solution of the labour problem and treats of " the reduction of the need for agricultural labour ". There has also been a particularly careful exainination of the opportunities there woidd be for replacing manual agricultural labour by mechanical motive power and for using agricultural implements and machines which would economise labour, the estimated expense of employing motors and machines, as compared with that of human labour, being of course taken as basis. Researches as to agricultural yield were made by means of single- entry and double-entry_agricultural book-keeping. The statistics collec- 20 SWITZERI^ANU - CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION ted as a result of book-keeping increase every year in volume and value. By this means it has been possible to undertake new researches, as into modifications of wealth, the influence of grouping lands on the results of agriculture, the relations between the capital invested in real estate and the profit derived from land, etc. The secretariat presented in a very concise form its customary report on the revenue derived from Swiss agriculture in 1915. Care was taken to emphasize the effect of two years of war. In 1916 the secretariat was commissioned by the Swiss Society of the Friends of Apiculture to check and examine the book-keeping of apiciilturists. The Office of Valuation of the Swiss Peasant's Union continued to draw on the results of the secretariat's researches in valuing farms. The secretariat also placed the results of its researches at the disposal of the newly founded Office of Rural Buildings. Finally the secretariat furnished much infor- mation especially on the subject of taxation for the war tax. On the occa- sion of the preparations for a revision of the customs tariff it undertook a special enquiry into the revenue derived from Swiss vineyards. The ex- amination of the facts thus collected gave verj' interesting results, and it was therefore decided to continue these researches § 2. Other work: The war tax. relations with THE international INSTITUTE OF AGRICULTURE. We have already explained in this Review the results of the researches and proposals of the secretariat as regarded the war tax (i). In igi6 the union continued its effort in the direction of judiciously interpreting the problem of valuing live stock with a view to the war tax. The secretariat also undertook this year to act as intermediary be- tween the International Institute of Agriculture and Germany, Austria, Hungary, Bulgaria and Turkey. (i) Iniernational Review of Agricultural Economics, June 1916, page 40. MISCElvIvANEOUS INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IX VARIOUS COUNTRIES. BRITISH INDIA. THE PROGRESS OF AGRICUI,TURAI, CO-OPERATION IN INDIA IN 1915-1916. — Report on the Working of the Co-operative Societies' Act in Burma for the year ended ^oth June 1916 Rangoon, Government Printing, 1917 ; Annual Report on the Working of Co-operative Societies in the United Provinces of Agra and Oudh for the year 1915-1916, Allahabad, Govern- ment Press, 1916 ; Report on the Working of the Co-operative Societies Act in the Madras Presidency i» .1915-1916, Madras, Government Press, 1916 ; Report on the Working of the Co-operative Societies in Coorg for the year ending 30tli June igi6, Mercara, The Coorg District Press, 1916. In our issue for April we published .an article on the progress of agri- cultural co-operation in India in 1914-1915. We will here give some data as to the development of co-operation in certain provinces in 1915-1916. I. Burma. During this year co-operation has made marked progress in Burma. After two years during which a certain repression was exercised expansion has been allowed. In the twelve months the total number of co-operative societies has increased by 50 per cent., passing from 1,490 to 2,251 ; while the total number of members has risen from 39,134 to 51,356, the working capital from Rs. 84.77 lakhs to 106.82 and the management and working expenses from Rs. 1.05 lakhs to Rs. 1.48. The subdivision of over-large itnions has raised their number from 112 to 189 and the increase in effi- ciency has been proportionate. The number of AgncuUiiral Credit Societies passed from 1,252 to 1,685 and that of their membrs from 30,130 to 36,494. Their working capital, exclusive of advances by the State, rose from Rs. 36,47,302 to Rs. 47,04,933 and their total reserve funds from Rs. 4,39,924 to Rs. 6,34,985. The for- mation of the Central Reinsurance Society at Mandalay led to an increase in the number of Cattle Insurance Societies from 63 to 305 and a propor- tionate increase in their membership. There were 46 non-agricultural societies on 30 June 1916 as against 43 on 30 June 1915. The ordinary rate of interest charged on loans by the Central Banks was 9 per cent. 22 INFORMATION REI.ATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The number of agricultural societies per 10,000 of the population was on 30 June igi6 just under three for Burma proper, but 25,15 and 8, respec- tively, for the Kyaukse, Shwebo and Pakokku districts (i). These three districts, in which co-operation was strongest, had, respectively, one agri- cultural society for every 800, 1520 and 1570 occupied acres, excluding fallows ; and Burma proper had one for each 7,100 acres (2). Since outside money was tight as an effect of the war, members depend- ed more than usual on their societies for credit. Crop prices were more- over generally lower than before the war. As a result the average loan to members of agrictdtural societies increased from Rs. 132 to Rs. 142. Tliis considerable rise was however less than the average increase per mem- ber of owned capital in such societies during the year. 2. UnHTED PROVINCES OF AGRA AND OUDH. The following table shows the general progress of the co-operative movement in the United Provinces in 1915-1916. Number of Societies Number of Members Working Capital I July 30 June 1916 I July 1915 30 June 1916 I July 1915 30 June 1916 Central 58 2,716 188 58 2,949 182 ! 8,';o2 i^^i^ Rs. 61,54.725 49,77,430 4.58,773 Rs. 64,39,838 51,32,044 4,62,969 Agricultural, primary. . , Non-agricultiiral, primary 101,511 6.270 106,333 6,918 Total . . . 2,962 3,189 116,283 118,864 1.15.90,928 1,20,34,851 The following table gives the sources of the assets of the primarj' societies and shows their progress. The figures refer to thousands of rupees. I,oans from central societies .... 11 t> non -members « « government Shares and deposits of members . . Profits and reserve fimds. Total 1910-11 1911-12 1912-13 1913-14 1914-15 1^15-16 1,97 39 3,20 1,78 21,60 14,28 21,821 31,31 2,41 24 4.35 2,07 30.89 4.44 17 5,29 2,90 44,11 40.58 4,45 13 7,30 3.96 56.42 38.06 3,10 10 9,26 5.44 55.96 37,84 1.95 6 11,00 7.06 57.91 (i) In 1912 this proportion was 26 for Germany, 23 for Denmark, 55 for Belgium, 9 for Italy and 8 for France. (2) Belgium, France, Germany, Denmark and Italy had, respectively, one ag^cultural society for every 943, 8,226, 3,058, 5,287 and 3,96.) cultivated acres. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 23 This table shows that the accutnidated savings of peasant members are beginning to assume respectable proportions. The continuation of the war naturally had a profound effect on co- operation in these provinces. Generally speaking it took the form of vague uneasiness and a half-conscious disinclination to part with money or its equivalent, but in the latter part of the year there was a recovery in this respect and much of the equilibrium disturbed by the war was restor- ed. The cotton crop was small owing to the low prices of the previous year and the rain and floods of September. The other crops did not enable the cultivator to recover am^ of th ground lost in the two previous years. When the year closed the indebtedness of members to primary societies had increased bj^ Rs. 95,000 ; and the sum overdue had reached 17.70 lakhs, having increased by Rs. 70,000. 3. Madras. There were 1600 co-operative societies in the Presidencj^ on 30 June 1915 and 1800 on 30 June 1916. The number of new societies formed during the year was 263 but 63 earlier societies were cancelled. The societies were chiefly' active in the matter of affording credit. Generally speaking the work of the year was the further consolidation of the credit movement by investing societies with the right of shareholding and the function of supervision. . On 30 June igi6 there were 29 administrative unions of societies — without counting Banking Unions, the Madras Provin- cial Co-operative Union and the South Arcot District Supervising Union — having 604 societies as their members ; while 608 societies were shareholders in Central Banks. The following table makes clear the position at this date: Kind of Society Number of Societies Number of Members Working Capital I July 1915 30 June 1916 I July 20 June 1915 1916 I July 191 5 30 Jime 1916 Central societies Agricultural societies . . Nod -agricultural societies 30 1,446 124 (I) II 1,601 157 1,770 90,088 27,603 1.568 100,761 34,565 Rs. 58,73,402 64,52,631 17.^3,389 Rs. 70,70,062 74.95,149 23,23,622 Total . . . 1,600 1,769 119,461 136,894 1,40,89,422 1,68,88,833 (i) Plus 31 unions, the 604 'societies affiliated to which have a total capital of Rs. 34,34,593. At the end of 1915-1916 the indebtedness of members to agricultural societies was Rs. 56,79,837 as against Rs. 50,85,356 at the close of the pre- 24 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION vious 3^ear. At the former date the sum overdue was Rs. 10,44,010, at the latter Rs. 9,45,369. Proportionately therefore there was a sUght improve- ment. The amount of loans granted for productive purposes was again higher than in the previous year, being 19.08 lakhs of rupees while the total loans amounted to 33.81 lakhs. The percentage of such total lent for productive purposes was thus 56.43 as aginst 56,88 in 1914-1915. The number of loans for terms of less than a year had diminushed and that of those for terms of more than two 3'ears had increased. This is a sign that the so- cieties begin better to understand the distinction between short and long- term loans. The earlier tendency was to look upon all credit operations as made for a year only but renewable in case of need. 4. COORG. The number of co-operative credit societies in Coorg remained the same as in 1914-1915 ; but 51 new members were enrolled, the capital rose from Rs. 1,15,500 to Rs. 1,22,168 and the reserv^e fund from Rs. 23,514 to Rs. 28,554. Nc> loans were taken from outsiders or government, and de- bentures amounting to Rs. 1,490 were redeemed. Although the Cattle Insurance Societies are now in the fourth year of their existence the public still view them with some distrust. Briefly the position is as follows : 391 head of cattle are insured ; 27 pohcies have been re- deemed to the value of Rs. 278 ; the reserve fund has risen from Rs. 590 to Rs. 1,030 ; and the total capital is Rs. 4,590 and is invested in the co-oper- ative credit societies at 8 per cent, interest. vSonie of the co-operative crecht societies have recognized that the payment of dividends to their shareholders does not encourage thrift and that it would be better to use this money to pay premiums for cattle insurance. It is hoped that the new ruling to this effect will add new members to the cattle insurance so- cieties. GERMANY. TIIK FEDERATION OF POEISTI CO-OPERATIVE SOCIETIES IN THE PROVINCEsS OF POSN.\NIA AND WEST PRUSSIA IN 191^. — Statistische Korrespondenz, 24 De- ceuibcr 191 5, Kerlin. Publication of the Royal Statistical Land Office (Kogl. Siatistisches J^andesamt) (i). This federation represents all the Polish co-operative societies in Pos- nania and West Prussia. The German co-operative societies in these provinces have their own federations, while the sixteen Polish co-oper- (i) Siatistisches iiber den Vcrhaud der Ermerbs- und WirtscJiaftsgenosscnschaften der Pro- vin-.en Posen und Wcstbreusscn. infor:matiox relating to co-operation and association 25 ative societies of Silesia belong to no federation. This Polish federation was formed in 1871, and was registered and granted the right of revision on 14 July 1892. At the end of 1914 it had 301 members as follows : 208 co-operative societies of credit 61 22 4 3 3 for purchase and sale subdivision consumption the construction of dwellings of trades. i) of these 208 credit societies 199 had unlimited and only nine li- mited liability. The latter were formed after the law of i88g, allowing the creation of co-operative societies of such type, was in force. The co-operative credit societies had in all 129,448 members or an average of 622 for each society. The minimum membership of a society was fifty-one, the maximum 6,554. I'he trades of members were as follows (i) ; 85,848 (68.63 P^r cent.) were agriculturists ; 24,858 (19.87 per cent.) " artisans ; 14,391 (11.50 per cent.) " traders and members of va- rious trades. In the agriculturists' group small landowners predominated being re- presented by 76,776 members. Of that of the artisans more than half — 14,147 — were also landowners. It is interesting to note that almost all the societies comprised members of different trades, those which were composed of members of only one trade being ver}' rare. This is due to the fact that most of them were situated in towns and included a town and the surrounding villages in their sphere of action. Their working capital amounted to 320,275,969 marks, being made up as follows : Share capital 26,280,839 marks reserve fund 15.155-934 individual deposits 271,013,287 current accounts in banks 7,825,909 320,275,969 marks (i) The data for two co-operative societies are laddng. 47,664,250 marks than 5,000,000 2 to 5,000,000 I " 2,000,000 500,000 1,000,000 100,000 " 500,000 less than 100,000 26 INFORMATION REIvATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION The working capital of individual societies varied enormously, as appears from the following figures : I co-operative society had a working capital of 12 " " " " " " " more 26 " " " " " " " from 51 50 59 The working capital of the limited liability was much larger than that of the unlimited liability societies. The number of depositors was 234,351, most of them peasants. Accord- ing to their form the deposits represented short-term liabilities, but in fact most of them were for long terms for the peasants do not withdraw their deposits except to buy land. The total assets of the 208 co-operative credit societies amounted to 320,275,969 marks made up as follows : bills of exchange 280,126,736 deposits in banks 15,317,472 in hand 3,465,170 various assets 21,366,591 The Polish co-operative societies usually grant credit, even in the case of mortgage loans and even although the loans are for long terms — three to ten years — in the form of bills of exchange. The co-operative society reserves the right to exact repayment before the term expires, if the debtor do not pay his redemption quotas regularly or if his solvency diminish. The profits realized amounted to 16,901,249 marks, 16,510,459 marks being interest exacted from debtors. The total expenditure amounted to 14,174,888 marks, 11,829,068 marks being interest paid to depositors and banks and 1,874,324 marks costs of administration. The net profits rea- lized by 202 co-operative societies amounted to 2,988,198 marks of which the share of six societies was 261,836 marks. Of all the net profits, 1,390,149 marks were distributed among the members and the rest paid into the re- sers'e fund. 2) The so-called " Rolnik " (agriculturists') co-operative societies for purchase and sale were first formed in 1894, but began to develop on a solid basis only in 1900. At the end of 191 4 there were in Posnania and West Prussia seventy Polish co-operative societies for purchase and sale of which sixty-one, hav- ing 9,733 members, belong to the Polish federation. All have limited lia- bility. The shares are from 20 to 50 marks, and each of them involves lia- INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 27 bility for five times its amount so that the extent of liability incurred by a share varies from 100 to 250 marks. No member may have more than ten shares. Most of the members are agriculturists. Data as to their working capital were furnished by only fifty-seven of these societies. The capital held by these societies amounted to 2,025,012 marks including 934,748 marks of paid-up share capital and 1,090,264 marks of reserve fund. The liability of the members extended to 9,926,000 marks. The societies also disposed of capital belonging to outsiders formed by de- posits of individuals and credit obtained from co-perative credit societies. Until 1908 private deposits provided the larger part of the working capital. In that year the general meeting passed a resolution that in future the so- cieties should accept fewer deposits from individuals and increase the sum of the credit afforded to them by co-operative credit societies. In conse- quence the societies for purchase and sale, in order to obtain larger credit from the credit societies, formed with them a species of personal union, admitting to their administrative councils two or three members of the administrative council of a credit society. At the end of 1914 the socie- ties' debt was 12,532,526 marks, one third being deposits of individuals and two thirds on current account with credit societies. These societies for purchase and sale undertake two kinds of business : they buy for their members goods necessary to agriculture (seeds, manures, forage) ; and they sell agricultural produce on commission. Their business of the latter kind is the more important, the selling being also practised by the co-operative credit societies and the agricultural circles. Their total turnover amounted to 46,000,000 marks, 28,000,000 marks standing for sales and 18,000,000 marks for purchases. 3) The co-operative societies for subdivision were first formed in 1890. Today there are altogether thirty-one of them and twenty-two be- long to the Polish federation. All the societies for subdivision have limited liability. Shares are from 100 to 500 marks and each involves liability for from two to five times its amount. The total membership of the societies belong- ing to the federation was 5,070. The members are mostly agriculturists, large or small proprietors ; but the so-called burgher societies include as members a certain number of traders and artisans and even some profes- sional men. Their capital amounted to 11,422,092 marks, made up of a share capi- tal of 7,533,970 marks and a reserve fund of 3,888,152 marks. They also receive very large credit from the co-operative credit societies and from the Federal Bank and other Polish and German banks. The deposits of out- siders form a mininumi of their working capital. lyike the societies for purchase and sale they often enter into a personal union with the co-op- erative societies in their respective districts. Their business is of two kinds : i) They regulate the mortgage debts of landowners ; 28 INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 2) They buy large properties, divide them into small lots, and resell them to Polish settlers. The data as to their business in 1914 have not been published. 4) The statistics for 1914 supply figures only as to the membership of the consumers', the trades' and the building societies. The ten co-oper- tive societies of these three kinds comprised 5,811 members. UNITED STATES. ra'E A'Mh'.RlCA'S SOCmTY OF EQVITY. — The Grain Growers' Guide, Winnipeg, ii April 1917. Founded in 1902 at Indianopolis, Indiana, the American Society of Equity is one of a number of kindred bodies working in the central and north- western States for better organization among farmers. From 1902 to 191 1 it had tremendous ups and downs — a series of successes and failures. Its growth has been ver\^ rapid in the last four years. The membership is now 100,000. It has 7,146 local unions and is operating in fourteen vStates — Kentucky, Indiana, Ilhnois, Wisconsin, Iowa, Minnesota, North Da- kota, South Dakota, Nebraska, Wyoming, Montana, Oregon, Washington and Idaho — and has scattered members in other places. Under the riiles of this society a count}^ union comprises five local unions and a State union a minimum of five county unions and 500 members. In Nebraska and Wyoming there are branches of the National Office which is situated at Wausaw in Wisconsin. The subscription for a new member is now §4 a year, of which 50 cents go to the local union, 15 cents to the county union, 35 cents to the State, 50 cents to the National Office, 50 cents either to the State or to National Equity papers and §2 to the State for organizing purposes. So far the work of the American Society of Equity has been mainly educative and has been carried on through meetings of local unions, fiter- ature, organizers or otherwise, much as is the educative work of the Grain Growers' Associations in Western Canada. This side of the enterprise seems indeed to have overshadowed its business side, for until the last two years little was done to develop the business organization. A little more than a j-ear ago the central organization estabHshed the American Co-operative Association which is the business organization of the American Society of Equity. It is organized under the Wisconsin State laws. It has already estabUshed several branches and transacted a large amount of business. Its first enterprise was to pubHsh The Organized Farmer of which the first issue appared on 14 January 1915. The large business that has developed has secured for the association the very lowest possible prices and enabled it to sell to its members approx- imately at the prices charged by wholesalers to retailers. The quality of the goods is guaranteed, the customer being under no obligation to accept them if the quality be not good. INFORMATION RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 29 A large quantity of wool is marketed through the association and it goes to the manufacturers directly. This year co-operative canneries and co-operative driers are being established in the Pacific coast States for can- ning and drj'ing fruit. The stockholders of these co-operative societies are the organized farmers and 90 per cent, of them are members of the Ameri- can Society of Equity. The total capitalization is $250,000 of which $3,000 has been paid up. The Wisconsin vState Union of the American Society of Equity has about 400 local unions and carries on varied work. It buys supplies, and was able last year to secure a profit in spite of the narrow margin on which business is conducted. Coal, flour, fodder, twine, machinery and all kinds of groceries are handled in fiftj'-pound orders. The price of gluten fodder has thus been reduced to members of the union by nearly S9 a ton. The Wisconsin State Union publishes its own paper, Tlie Equity News. At present the association is organizing the Industrial Co-operative Union which will, as far as possible, deliver goods directly from the producer to the consumer. A company with a capitalization of half a million is being started, half the stock to be sold to producers and half to consumers in Milwaukee. One or two central receiving plants are being established and a number of distributing centres with rigs are being placed in different parts of the city. A consequent reduction in the cost of living is anti- cipated. The activities of the society of Equity vary in different States. In Min- nesota and Wisconsin the live stock shipping associations have had a great development, at least 200 of them being organized by this society alone. At Farmington in Minnesota a wool warehouse has been established ; and not only is a better price being secured for wool, but many excellent garments are being manufactured very cheaply and returned to the wool consigners at far lower prices than those for which they could bviy them elsewhere. In North Dakota the chief business has been in grain, and a fight steadily waged for some time with the Minneapolis Chamber of commerce has fi- nally residted in the establishment of a .separate exchange in St. Paul. Other States have dealt with special phases of the marketing and buj'ing problem. NOTICES REIvATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. GREECE. KAIylTSINAKIS (Dr. Jur. D. E.) : Die genossenschaftliche Beuegung in Griechenland (The Co-operative Movement in Greece). Balkan-Revue, No. 4-5, Year III, 1916. In 1 91 1 a new department, called the Ministry of National Economy, was created in Greece, and the State has since interv^ened more importantly than before in the country's economic life. In 1914 this department pro- posed a law as to co-operative societies which has had force since 24 Jan- uary 1915 and on which the article here cited bears. In drawing up the law the Greek legislature was influenced by the cha- racter of the co-operative movement in Germany, and therefore the measure presents a combination of Raiffeisen and Schulzte-Delitsch principles and reproduces almost literally many provisions of the German law of 1889 on co-operative purchase and labour {Erwerbs- und Wirtschajts genossenschajten) . But to some extent the Greek legislature took into account the special cir- cumstances of the country, and thus there are in the law certain devia- tions from the line traced by German principles. The following are the characteristic features of the Greek law : i) In the case of co-operative societies of everj^ kind, whether credit, agrictdtural, industrial or other, the law allows their formation on the prin- ciple of either limited or unlimited liability. The form selected has merely to be noted in the by-laws (article 22). As is known the rural co-operative societies, especially those which are credit societies, almost all have unli- mited liability. 2) In the matter of the territorial sphere of an association the Greek law adopts the principles of Raiflteisen, in that of the admission of members those of Schultze-Delitsch : thus the sphere of co-operative action is li- mited to a village or a commune, and the admission of members depends on the obligatory purchase of shares. The members of an unlimited liability society are obliged to pay the amount of one share, but the by-laws of a limited liability society may prescribe the subscription of two or even more shares (article 20). 3) Articles 14 to 67 and 68 of the law prescribe the obligatory for- mation of a reserve fund in accordance with Raiffeisen principles. Ten per cent, of the net profits are paid into the reserve fund annually, and such pay- ments cannot be interrupted until this fund becomes equal to the share capital. The reserve fund serves to cover eventual losses and may not be used as working capital. It is invested in State securities. It is considered XOTICES RELATING TO CO-OPERATION AND ASSOCIATION 3 1 to belong to the co-operative society in its capacity as a legal person and not to be the collective property of the members ; and therefore in case of liquidation it is not distributed to the members but is deposited in the Cen- tral Fund which remits it to any new co-operative society formed in the same place and with the same objects. Besides this regular reserve fund the law allows the creation of extraor- dinary reserve funds, which have however a quite different character being employable as working capital. They may be distributed among the mem- bers if the general meeting so decide. 4) The organs of a co-operative society are the council of administra- tion, the council of vigilance and the general meeting. The functions of the two former are honorary, only their technical officials being paid. In the general meeting of an unlimited liability society all the members have equal rights ; in that of a limited liability society the members are divided into two classes, those having one and those having two votes. 5) Articles 55 and 56 provide for the liquidation of societies. Iviqui- dation takes place : a) in response to a resolution passed by the general meeting; b) when a judgement on a legal point has to be executed ; c) in case of failure. When a liquidation is necessary liquidators are elected who are respon- sible for the conduct of the society's business until the liquidation has been effected. The law provides finally that wherever a case is not covered by its dispositions those of the codes of commerce and civil procedure shall be followed. Up to 31 December 1915 eighty-seven co-operative societies were created under the provisions of this law, namely sixty-one rural credit so- cieties, eighteen rural producers' societies which included eleven for the pro- duction of dried currants, and eight rural and urban labour societies. Of these eighty-seven societies only six had unlimited while eighty-one had limited liability. UNITED STATES. I . BI5XEI*Iy (J. A. ) and KERR (W. H.; : Business practice and accounts for cooperative STORES. U. S. Dept. Agr. Bull. 381 (1916), pp. 56, pi. i). The authors have outhned a simple and adequate system of records for co-operative retail stores and pointed out fundamental business methods that must be observ^ed to insiure success. They have discussed this subject under the headings of corporate records, statements and reports, operat- ing records, auditing, and office equipment. The bulletin outlines in de- tail the necessary records and statements essential to the proper conduct- ing of stores under a co-operative scheme and gives a large number of model forms. NOTICES RELATIXG TO CO-OPEIi^VTION AND ASSOCIATION 2. HUMPHRY (J. R.) and KERR (W. H.) : A system of accounts for live-stock shipping ASSOCIATIONS. (U. S. Dcpt. Agr. Bull. 403 (1916), pp. 14). In this bulletin types of shipping agencies and methods of financing shipping associations are described, together with methods of keeping the accoimts of such associations. The authors have outhned a system in which the only books of record required are a cash journal, consisting of a multi-column cash book and a journal combined, with provision for a de- tailed account of sales of supplies, and an ordinar\^ form of loose-leaf ledger. The}' also describe other forms that may be used, such as the shipping record envelopes, members' receipts, members' account sales, manifests, sales tickets, and cash receipts. Sample forms are included in the bulletin. 3. BEXEI/Iy (J. A.), MACPHERSON (H.) and KERR (W. H.) : A survey of typical co-op- ER.\TIVE STORES IN THE UNITED STATES. {U . S. Dept. Agr. Bul. 394 (l9l6),pp. 32, pls. 2). Data collected from sixty stores in ten States by the Office of Markets and Rural Organization in co-operation with the Oregon Agricultural Col- lege are reported and discussed. " The figures collected in this survey bring out the conclusion that the majority of the co-operative stores established are unsuccessful in achieving their main object — saving on purchases to members and a re- duction of the high cost of living. This conclusion is borne out by the supplementary notes collected from managers who could not apply statis- tics, and by notes on interviews with leaders who are acquainted with the store movement in whole sections which could not be covered in detail. But that there is one real service which the co-operative stores have per- formed seems to have been demonstrated again and again. Even in cases where stores have failed absolutely and gone into bankruptc}'' they have frequently been responsible for the introduction of improved business me- thods in the towns where they were established. They have had the effect of stimulating com])etition. In cases where the merchants have com- peted keenly against the co-operative store they have been compelled to adopt more efficient business methods. This has resulted in lower prices to every consumer in the locality and frequently in better prices to farmers on produce ". The authors believe that the conditions necessar\' for success are good leadership, capable management, favourable environment, and adequate legal safeguards, and that a lack of these is generally the cause of failure. A number of statistical tables, setting forth the various facts concerning the stores from which this survey was made, are included in the bulletin. NOTICES RELATING TO CO-OPER.\TION AND ASSOCIATION ^^ 4. GAIyPIN (C. J.) and SAWTELIvE (D. W.) : Rural clubs in Wisconsin [Wisconsin Sta Bill. 271 (1916) pp. 5S, figs. 22). The authors believe that to hve on good terms with others is a part of modern farming, as truly as to know how to farm, and that the higher level of efficiency is reached in the science and art of local agriculture when families know one another well and meet frequently. A strong circula- tion of ideas and impulses is deemed necessary to counteract discontent and the temptation to sell farms and move awa}^ from rural districts. The authors state that about one fifth of the farmers in Wisconsin are members of various rural clubs or attend their meetings. They have divided the rural clubs into four typical groups each of which they illus- trate by typical examples. The four groups are those of the farmers' family club, the farm men's club, the farm women's club, and the young folks' club. Part II: Insurance and Thrift UNITED STATES THK GENERAI, CONDITIONvS OF INSURANCE AGAINST FIRE AND THE DE\'EI,OPMENT OF MUTUAL INSURANCE. OPFICIAI, SOURCES: Valgren (V. N.), Investigator in Agricultural Insurance Office of Markets and Rural Orga- nization : — Farmers' Mutual Fire Insurance. Washington, Government Printing Office, 191 7. Potts (Rxifus M.) : Forty-Seventh Annual Insurance Report of the Insurance Superintendent of the State of Illinois. Farm Mutual Insurance Companies. OTHER SOURCES : Wentworth (Franklin H.), Secretary-Treasurer National Fire Protection Association: Ameri- can Fire Waste and its Prevention, in The Annals of th e American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. Iremiums estimated at $1,000,000 a year. b) Methods ol Determininii Rates. Risks to be covered by fire insurance were first rated bj'' means of a classification of buildings — for some time the only property insured — into groups, each risk included in a group taking its rate. With an increased appreciation of the multitude of differences in the construction, use and si- tuation of buildings and the nature and quality of substances, the classi- fications necessarily nmltiplied. It became impossible to obtain enough like risks to form a valid class ; there was the difficulty of classifying a building having diverse occupancies and congregated risks ; an ever-growing " miscel- laneous " group of heterogeneous and unrelated risks developed. The only groups which coiild be successfully rated were churches and dwelling-houses as to which there is a sufficient collection of data. From t868 onwards the schedule system was substituted in the United States for that of classification. This system atempts an analysis of fire UNITED STATES - INSURANCE AND THRIFT hazard into its component parts. The schedtale gives a Hst of the conditions for which an inspector should look, diminishing the probability that he will overlook defects or good points. A combination of judgements was obtained in determining the charges to be made for the particular risks dis- tinguished b}'^ the analysis. It might at least be expected that a smaller percentage of error would be present under such conditions than in the un- aided estimate of any individual inspector. The modern era of schedule rating may be said to begin with the pub- lication in 1893 of the Universal Mercantile Schedule, an attempt to devise a system of rating universally applicable and to render special schedules unnecessary. This schedule starts from a basis rate for a " standard " building in a " standard " city, such rate being 25 cents for every $100 of insurance. To decide what the rate shoidd be on a standard building in a given city this city is compared with the standard city. In order to find the rate for a given building its construction, occupancy and exposure must also be considered. The second important universal schedule, the Ana- lytic, presented a better formulated analysis of hazard. But both these schedules made practically no attempt to justify their results by statistics. An insistent demand at the Annual Convention of Insurance Commissioners that such neglect should be remedied resulted in the establishment b}^ the National Board of Fire Underwriters of an actuarial bureau to ascertain fire loss costs. Subsequently two new schedules were devised, one combin- ing some features of the Universal and the Analytic, the other designed to make use of the data collected by the foresaid actuarial bureau. The for- mer, the L. S- L. Schedule, or I^arter and I^emmon Rating System, has in particular two new features : it lays stress on the " burning degree " or degree of inflammability and on the influence of floor resistance. The E. G. R. Schedule, or Experience Grading and Rating Schedule, is an attempt to devise a method of ascertaining the total cost of insuring risks of varying character by an analysis of statistics of past experience. The method of procedure is : i) to ascertaiti the ratio of losses, expenses and a fair profit, to the insurance written on all risks in the United States ; 2) to obtain a similar ratio for the average risk in each particular State ; 3) to ascertain the ave- rage United States' rate on a risk of a specific class. The danger of inade- quate data as a basis for premiums is thus immensely reduced, while the risks in every State are rated in accordance with its particular experience. The E. G. R. schedule is plainly an endeavour, however successful or un- successful its results may be, to meet fairly the objections of critics to existing methods of measuring hazard. A few words may be said as to the collection of the data necessary to its application. On i January 1915 a standard classification was adopted and the actuarial bureau of the National Board of Fire Underwriters began a collection of experience from almost 190 companies, nearly one third of which were nmtual societies and not members of the National Board. The board's work has been much furthered by the co-operation of the insu- rance departments of a number of States. In May 1916, 236 companies were co-operating in the work, including 125 National Board companies, THE GENERAL CONDITIONS OF INSURANCE AGAINST FIRE 39 52 muttial companies, and 59 other companies. In 1915 about 650,000 loss reports were received and at the present rate there will be on file at the end of 1916 over a million reports of losses sustained and paid by members of the bureau. § 2. Farmers' mutual fire insurance. One of the most successful forms of rural co-operation in the United States is that of farmers' mutual fire insurance. Up to the present time however it has received but little general publicity. Few men, even among the farmers themselves, are aware of its importance. Many will be surprised therefore to learn that there are at present nearly 2,000 farmers' mutual fire insurance companies in the United States. These companies carry a total amount of insurance exceeding $ 5,250,000,000. The property on which this insurance is written is valued at more than $6,700,000,000 which is more than two fifths of the value of the insurable property in the forty- eight States. While mutual fire insurance in the United States dates from 1752, the first farmers' mutual fire insurance company came into existence about 1825. New England and the Middle Atlantic States saw the first attempts at this form of co-operation by farmers. It was soon shown that a consider- able saving in the cost of fire insurance could be effected by its means and the movement spread fairly rapidly from one community to another. By the middle of the century- a considerable number of farmers' companies of this kind were in existence, and more than half those now existing were organized before 1850. Most of these companies were incorporated under special charters and left to do business practically without guidance or supervision. Unfort- unately these co-called " farmers' mutuals " in some instances failed to limit themselves to the segregated risks of moderate value to which their vo- lume of business and their methods adapted them. Hence their record in this period is by no means one of uniform success. In spite -^^f this handicap the movement continued to extend westwards and southwards from the place of its origin. By 1875 there were about 400 farmers' mutuals and by 1900 there were at least 1700 of them. Their present number exceeds 1950. a) Legislation. The rapid extension of insurance on this plan after 1850 was due in no small measure to favourable legislation. The first farmers' mutual insu- rance law was passed by the State of New York in 1857. This law provided that twenty-five or more persons residing in any township of the State and owning a total of $ 50,000 worth of property which they desired to insure might form themselves into a mutual insurance company. They were al- lowed to insure only buildings and the goods contained therein. They could insure no city or village property and could not accept risks outside the T'\'rn:i) statics - ixsruwri', \\'i> 'niRii'T borders of tlie home township. The>' could write insurance against loss or damage by fire only. This hiw, thf)uglu evidently too restrictive in its provisions regarding business territor}- and the risks that might be assumed, ai)pears to have become the model for similar laws in the north central States generally, and for some twelve other vStates situated further south or west. The early New York law was repealed in 1862 ond it was not until 1879 that a second law, somewhat more lil)eral in its provisions, was enacted. In the meantime Wisconsin, Illinois, Michigan, Iowa, Minnesota, Ohio and Indiana had enacted farmers' nmtual fire insurance laws. These laws and also the second New York law generally permitted that a number of con- tiguous townshi]is or an entire county should form a ])usiness territory. All kinds of farm ])ro])erty might be insured and the lightning hazard as well as that of tire might be assumed. h",.\ce])t the Indiaiia law the}- dif- fered from the New York law of 1879 in that they placed the companies thus organized under the supervision of the res])ective State insurance depart- ment". This stejj was not taken by Ntw York until igog. By i8go practi- cally ev-.-ry State in the Middle West and several of those in the South had a farmers' mutual fire insurance law. The present laws upon this subject, while similar in nuiny respects, are by no means equally complete or practical in all their provisions. It may hv said that at ])resent twenty-five States have fairly satisfactory farmers' mutual fire insurance laws. vSeveral other States have scattered provi.sions in their laws as to fire insurance in general which ai)ply ])articularly to farmers' mutual com])anies. In a few States, having laws which make no special reference to farmers' insurance organizations, the companies ope- rate either under special charters or under laws api)lying to all classes of mutual fire insurance com])anies. In .six States, all in the South or South- West, no record of companies of this kind has been found. The older farmers' mutual insurance laws have in practically ever}' instance been variously amended. The trend of these amendments has been to enlarge the business territory permitted and give more scope to the activities of the companies. In several instances they are allowed to ojjcrate in an entire State. As a rule however the laws prescribe for them territories varying from one to five counties. While many of the companies have availed themselves of the provisions allowing such enlargement, the great majority still operate in a single country while a few still confine them- selves to a single township. There has been a growing tendency, especially in the Southern States, to allow the farmers' nuitual societies to include windstorm among the hazards they assume. Mr. \'. N. Valgren states in the i)aper cited at the beginning of this article that the ])ractice is not to be reconnuended. " Each group of farm buildings, and to a considerable extent each building within the group, is a distinct and sei)arate risk with respect to the fire and lightning hazards, but this is not true with respect to the windstorm hazard... The practice which is rapidly gaining favour in the Middle West of o])crating a State-wide windstorm insurance company through the co-operative efforts THIC r,i:xi:RAI. C<1\1>1TI()XS OV IXSrUAXCK A(;ainst itrk 41 of the local lire iusuraucc coiiipauies would udil much to the stabihty aud safety of the fanners' mutual organizations in any State where combined protection is now offeroil by the local mutuals ". b) 1 1)1 port ancc The total amount of insurance carried by the 1,947 farmers' nuitual fire insurance companies in existence on i January iQis.the latest date for which relatively complete statistics arc at hand, was ap]iroximately $5,264,119,000. The total amount paid for losses during 1914 was Sio,70(),()5i and the exj)enses of operation were .'53,i38,()49, making the total cost of this insurance $13,905,300. From these figures it may be seen that the average cost ])er c; 100 of insurance in all these companies was about 26 cents. The farmers' nuitual companies almost without exception limit the amount of the insurance written to either three fourths or two thirds of the actual value of the jiroperty. A reasonable allowance for this fact shows the total value of the farm property insured by these companies to be approxi- mately $(), 730,000,000. The total value of all insurable farm pro])erty in the forty-eight States on i January 1915 was, as nearly as can be estimated, 815,880,000,000. This would indicate that nearly 42 ^/., per cent, of all insurable farm ])ro]ierty in the forty-eight vStates of the Union was insured in the farmers' mutual fire insurance companies. The following table shows the geographical distribution of these eomi)a- nies, the total amount of their insurance in force on 1 January 1915, and the average cost of $100 of insurance during 1914 : Geographical Division New Kngland Middle Atlantic East North Central West North Central South Atlantic East South Central . . West S » second » » » » 2.27 2.19 2.41 These figures show an irregular but gradual increase in the loss per thou- sand column, the cost for the second being greater than that for the first five years. The circumstance seems to be due to the considerable propor- tion of so-called " mysterious fires ", many of which could be avoided by 46 UNITED STATES - INSURANCE AND THRIFT precautions and inspection. One mutual fire insurance company in Illinois classified the causes of the fires for which it paid indemnities as follows : Railway engine .... i Bonfires 3 Furnace i Children playing with matches 5 Spontaneous combustion i vSparks on roof 12 Deliberate incendiarism . 2 Kerosene and gasoline ... 12 Farm engine 2 Defective flues 23 Smoking 2 Unknown 24 Tramps 2 lyightning 100 Parlour match .... 3 Thus in this particular case 16 per cent, of the fires had unknown causes. The necessity of ascertaining the causes of fires in order to take the needed preventive measures is evident. The government of Illinois has not neglected fire prevention but formed in igii the Fire Marshal's Department which is divided into three sections. The section of publicity and education conducts public meetings at which the question of fire prevention is discussed and the people instruc- ted as to their personal responsibilit3^ The section of investigation inves- tigates the causes of fires which appear suspicious in order that prosecutions for fraud and arson may be conducted. The section of inspection educates the people to protect their property. In June 1914 more fires caused by lightning were reported to the department than ever before in one month, namely 120 fires which caused a total loss of § 202,637. -^^ the same month the total number of fires reported was 975 and they caused a total loss of $ 957,014. Thus lightning was responsible for 12 per cent, of the fires and 21 per cent, of the loss. The great majority of the fires occurred in rural districts and the bulk of the losses was borne bj^ the farmers. The co-operation of the mutual companies would be most valuable, and since the interests of farmers are directly at stake it may be hoped that the campaign undertaken in its favour will meet with good results. The experience of commercial companies has convinced the farmers' mutual fire insurance companies of the need for a standard fire insurance policy. Mr. E. W. Monnier spoke at the meeting on this subject as follows : " We have in the State of Illinois 220 mutual fire insurance companies and 12 mutual windstorm companies and perhaps as many forms of policy and different by-laws. That such conditions exist and that mutual insurance companies are successful iinder such conditions can onh^ be accounted for from the fact that mutual insurance conducted under most an^^ condition cannot fail to save money when we compare the actual rate of loss in the State with the rate charged by old line companies, the actual rate charged by old line companies being almost or quite double the actual cost of insurance. Conservatively speaking 40 per cent, is saved by the members of mutual companies as compared with the cost of purchasing old line insurance. Can we not do even better than this ? To me it seems an easy matter to increase the saving from 40 per cent, to at least 60 per cent, but I do not THE GENERAI. CONDITIONS OF INSURANCE AGAINST FIRE 47 believe the result will be attained unless it be by co-operation and to attain this a standard policy should be adopted by all mutual fire and windstorm insurance companies...* Comparatively few mutual companies classify risks... I have encouraged for several years a lower rate of premium — but without success as 3'et — in the company that I represent on property that is pro- perly protected by hghtning rods... The diversity which obtains in policies was illustrated during a discus- sion on the insurance of town property by farmers' companies. The old prejudice against insuring town and village property on the same plane as farm pro])erty is fast disappearing. In towns there are better and more quickly attainable facilities for fighting fires. Detached town dwellings are liable to be less heavily insured than improved and completely stocked farms. Such a farm is so valuable that insurance on it is easily written above the legal limit. That town property is not so readily destroyed as farm property is proved by the fact that some old line companies charge the higher rate for farm property. The mutual companies follow individual principles in the matter. One insures town buildings which are separated from others by as much as eighty feet. In the five years ending 31 December 1914 its losses on town property were almost negligible, being only $75. The representative of another compan^^ stated at the meeting that his experience of twenty years had taught him that small villages gave better risks than farms, but he objected to insurance in large towns. Another company insures village pro- perty separated by 100 feet from other buildings, and yet another village property so separated by 25 feet. One company at first insured only houses situated 100 feet from other buildings but has reduced this interval suc- cessively to 50, 30 and finally 15 feet. Similarly some companies insure motor-cars and farm machinery while others refuse to do so. One company insures motor-cars as farm machinery for two thirds of their value in the first year, one fourth less in the second year, one fourth less in the third year, and one fourth of the original insurance in the fourth and fifth years. Another company insures them at a value of not more than $ 400 and pays two thirds of the appraised value if the machine is destroyed. Yet another insures them for two thirds of their value in the first year and 20 per cent, less in the second. The necessity of providing a standard insurance policy, to replace the present diverse collection, is therefore evident and will gradually be re- cognized by the rural population. Facilities for insurance are defective, and this fact together with the tendency of mutual companies to assume too great risks . may have formid- able consequences. There is therefore a demand for such a modification of the law as will allow the farmers' mutual fire insurance companies to share their surplus of risks. This tendency to unification and co-operation among the mutual com- panies cannot fail to be to them a new and powerful factor of progress. Part III: Credit RUSSIA. THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE LAND BANK FOR THE NOBILITY IN 1915. OFFICIAIv SOURCES : OxieTH rocy;a,apcTBCHHaro 3eMeJii>Haro BaHKa (Report of the State Land Bank for //ze A''o6j7t7y), Pctrograd, 1906 to 1915, the last issue. MaTepbHJibi no CTaTiiCTiiK'lfi aBHJKema SeM.neBJiaTi.'feHia [Material for Statistics as to the Transmission cf Lands) Petrograd, 1906-1910. A^HTejiBHOcrb rocyj;apcTBeHHaro SBMejibnaro Jl^BopHHCKaro BanKa {Activity of the State Land Bank for the Nobility) Public annual leports resumed in the official weekly review of the Ministry of Finances, 1910-1916, B-fccTHMKi. OnHaHCOBt, I^poJiBim- JieHHOCTH H ToproBJiii. V. MoRATCHEVSKY : CejibCKO-xosaticTBeHiibiH KpeAnxTj Bt. Poccin (Agricultural Credit in Russia) Petrograd, 191 o. OTHKR SOURCES : iMiGULiN : Arpapiibiii BOnpoct (The Agrarian Question) Petrograd, 1906. RiCHTER : 3a;50.7yKeHH0CTb HacTHaro seMJieBJiajii'feHia (The Indebtedness of Landed Property) Petrograd, 1897. SviATLovsKY : Mo6iiJi3aii;iH aeMeJibHoii co6TTBeHHOCTii B-b Poccin (The Transmis- sion of Landed Property) Vetro^rsid, 1911. Drosdov : CyJibSbi flBopHHCKaro aeMJieBJiaji.'feHiH (The Future of the Landed Property of the Nobility) in CoBpeMeHHbiH Miprb. (The Modern World) Nos. 10 and 11, 1916. Zak : KpecTbHHCKiM IloBeMejibiibiii BanK-b (The Bank of the Agriculturists) Mos- cow, 1911. The State Land Bank of the Nobihty has recently published a report for 1915. From this it appears that the 3^ear was characterized by a dimi- nution of the bank's mortgage business. This business had gained a really notable ascendancy in the beginning of the twentieth century but diminished under the reaction from the influence of the war. § I. Mortgage Business. The number of loans made on mortgages by the Bank of the Nobility in 1 913, the time when the rise of which we have spoken reached its highest point, was 1425. THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE EAND BANK FOR THE NOBILITY 49 If this figure be compared with the number of mortgage loans made by the bank in 1915, namely 470, a serious retrogression in mortgage business will be observed. This was, as the report states, a result of the war, which influenced the whole of this year. It also depended to some extent on the ordinance of the Committee of Finances of '23 July 1914 which Hmits mortgage business. The following table may give a more precise idea of the general de- velopment in recent years of this bank's mortgage business : Table I. •- Mortgage Business of the Bank of the Nobility from iqiT to 1915 (in roubles). Estimated value of Niunber Area mortgaged properties Sums lent of mortgaged ' - — — " " ~^ "" ' ^ — '^ — - ' ^ Year loans — total by deciatine total by deciatine deciatines(i) roubles (2) roubles roubles roubles 1911 1355 1,101,685 152,166,685 138 88,842,600 81 1912 i486 1,195,873 190,358,777 159 109,3x4,100 92 1913 1425 1.536,873 253,726,195 165 146,082,000 95 1914 1292 1,123,808 197,590,208 176 114,420,400 T02 1915 470 40>9O- 71.553.744 144 4^,827,300 84 This table shows that far fewer loans were made in 1915 than in 1914, and fewer by still more than during the years before the war. That which however chiefly characterizes 1915 is the sudden interruption in the con- stant rise of the average estimated value of the deciatine. The fall of its average value is seen to be more remarkable if it be compared t6 the special estimated average value which continued to rise even in 1915. Thus in 1911 this was 105 roubles a deciatine, in 1912 it was 125 roubles, 159 rou- bles in 1913 and 160 roubles in 1915. As the normal estimate is based on the average cost of land in a locality, and the special estimate on a spe- cial and detailed survey of the properties concerned, the different courses of the normal and the special estimates are an index to the different influence which the economic crisis caused by the war has had on farms in general, which in their large majority belong to the peasants, and on the property of the hereditary nobility. The war has deprived the peasants of a large number of labourers whom it has been impossible to replace. Hence has arisen the diminution in the average estimated value of lands, an important percentage of which it has been impossible to cultivate or to cultivate adequately. The needed labour on the lands of the nobility was however partly supplied bj^ prisoners of war and in some provinces by the forced labour of peasants. During 1915 the increase in the special estimated value was however slight in comparison with its increase in preceding years, and this fact and (i) I deciatine = 2.698 acres. (2) I rouble = 2.1333s. at par. 50 RUSSIA - CREDIT the diminution in the normal average estimated va.\ue are explained by a very considerably lessened bn34ng and selling of lands as a consequence of the war. The figure representing the purchase of land b}^ peasants, who are the great m.ajority of the purchasers, was less than a third of such figure for the preceding year. The development of the mortgage credit easily obtained from the Agriculturists' Bank much stimulated the pur- chase and sale of lands. The peasants, seeking to satisf}' their " land hunger ", caused prices to rise to unprecedented heights, yet further raised artificiall}' — conditions which have been experienced in other European countries. The war caused these purchases and sales to diminish and thus caused also a fall in the price of land. Of the 470 loans made by the Bank of the Nobility in 1915, 131 of the total sum of 3,864,200 roubles were secured b}^ first mortgages on a total area of 71,502 deciatines of land previously unburdened in relation to the bank. The remainder, namely 339 loans of a total sum of 37,963,000 rou- bles were granted on renewed or complementary mortgages ou 425,399 de- ciatines of land already mortgaged to the bank. The following table gives a more exact idea of the indebtedness of the lands mortgaged to the bank : Table II. — Indebtedness of the Lands mortgaged to the Bank from 1906 to 1 91 5. In relation to the total In relation to the total number of mortgaged properties mortgaged area Years Properties Properties Unmortgaged Area already mimortgaged already mortgaged area mortgaged — % % % % 1906 . . 32 68 39 61 1907 . . 22 78 8 02 1908 . . 25 75 12 88 1909 . . 20 80 12 88 I9IO . . 24 76 13 82 I9II . . 21 79 12 88 I9I2 . . 24 76 17 83 I9I3 . 22 78 18 82 I9I4 . . 23 77 27 73 1915 . . 21 79 10 90 Since the Bank of Nobility first began business it has granted loans secured by mortgages on lands already largely mortgaged, so that it has reduced the terms on which the nobility can obtain land credit from batiks and individuals. During the years of crisis the activity of the bank was limited to support of the properties economically weakest, that is to soy already burdened with mortgages. This phenomenon is to be observed in 1907 when the percentage of the area already mortgaged was 92 and in advance of all precedents. The year 1915 conies very near to 1907, its THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE LAND BANK FOR THE .NOBILITY 5 1 corresponding percentage being go and indicative of the seriousness of the crisis of 1915 for the landed property of the nobiUty. The number of loans granted on the security of normal mortgages was only 114 or 24 per cent., while the other moitgages, 75 per cent, of the total number, were made after a special estimate. The total percentage of loans thus made during the year was 90. The total sum for which the 470 persons, whose applications were accepted, apphed as loans was 46,951,000 roubles. The bank could grant 41,827,000 roubles or 89 per cent, of the sum demanded. During the last six years the relation between the demand and the supply of loans was as follows : Table III. — Relation between the Demand and Supply of Loans. Number of cases in which the whole sum demanded was lent Sum lent per 100 roubles demanded roubles 86 52 92 51 92 40 84 46 93 49 89 57 I9I0 I9II I9I2 I9I3 I9I4 I9I5 It is apparent from this table that during these six years the whole sum demanded was lent in the largest percentage of cases. The bank sought to concentrate its aid on the neediest properties and was, in view of the crisis, obliged in many cases to lend the whole sum demanded. The average area of the properties mortgaged to the bank on i January 1915 was 498 deciatines ; that of those mortgaged afresh in 1915 was 546 deciatines. The greater part, namely 61.9 percent., of the latter belonged to the class ot medium-sized farms (from 100 to 1000 deciatines of culti- vable land) ; 23.6 per cent, were small farms of less than 100 deciatines ; and the remainder, namely 14.5 per cent., were large properties of more than 1,000 deciatines. Of the total area of the properties mortgaged in 1915, 60.8 per cent, belonged to the class of large properties (more than 1,000 deciatines of cultivable land) ; 36.8 per cent, to that of mediimi-sized properties and 2.4 per cent, to that of small properties. These data, if compared wdth those for the years from 1905 to 1915, confirm the statement that medium-sized properties have least |^X)wer of economic resistance. Table IV shows that it is exactly in periods of crisis, as in the j-ears from 1908 to 1910, or even more so in the period in which the consequences of a crisis are more felt, that the percentage of mortgaged properties of medium size rises ; for these properties are those which need most care and support in order that they may surmount a crisis. D-i RUSSIA - CREDIT Table IV. — Mortgaged Properties according to Size. Year Rdatively to number of mortgaged properties I,arge Medium-sized Small properties properties properties % % % Relatively to total area Large Medium-sized Small properties properties properties % % % 1906 . . 27.2 55-8 17.0 84-3 15.G 0.7 1907 . . 28.2 51-3 20.5 77-9 21. 1 I.O 1908 . . 16.2 62.0 21.8 59-7 38.1 2.0 1909 . 18.4 63.6 18.0 65.8 32.7 1-5 I9IO . . 13.2 60.4 26.4 68.1 29.8 2.1 I9II . . I6.I 56.0 27.4 71.6 26.4 2.0 I9I2 . 15-5 56.8 27-3 71.7 26.6 ^•7 I9I3 • 18.9 58.1 23.0 77-9 20.9 1.2 I9I4 . 16.7 57-1 26.2 77.0 21.7 1-3 I9I5 ■ 14-5 61.9 23.6 60.8 36.8 2.4 An examination of transactions in each district shows that large dis- tricts in which the capitaHst sj^stem of cultivating land is followed give most resistance to a crisis, and that resistance is comparatively weak where the large properties are still in the stage of primitive cultivation. In 1915 loans were secured by renewed inortgages on 399 properties having a total area of 425,339 deciatines and a value of 63,9x9,857 roubles. The total sum thus lent was 37,963,100 roubles, of which 23,825,600 rou- bles was the sum granted when the loan originated and was renewed, while the remaining 14,137,500 roubles or 60 per cnt of the total sum lent was the sum of the complement an," loans made at the time of renewal. Through- out the year onlj- one privileged loan was granted to the Russian nobles to enable the purchase of properties in the provinces of West and South- West Poland. This loan was of 150,000 roubles and the land bougbt had an area of 2,000 deciatines. The following table will give a more exact idea of the development of renewals of mortgages from 1901 to 1915. THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE LAND BANK FOR THE NOBILITY 53 Table V. — Renewals of Mortgages from igoi to i 915. Percentage Number Number Percentage Sums lent of sums lent of of loans of renewed on renewed Year loans on renewed loans roubles mortgages mortgages % % igoi . . 1950 894 46 26,549.500 62 1902 . . 184I 975 53 64,512,400 67 1903 . . 1549 858 55 66,523,700 73 1904 . . 1259 722 57 52,950,100 75 1905 . . 846 545 64 39,782,200 81 1906 . . 625 378 60 32,788,200 73 1907 . . 280 202 72 26,164,000 92 1908 . . 518 326 63 26,549.500 84 1909 . . 784 525 67 49,701,600 82 I9I0 . . 1248 802 64 87,125,400 72 I9II 1355 894 66 88,842,600 78 I9I2 . . i486 940 63 109,314,100 73 J9I3 . . 1425 948 66 146,082,000 71 I9I4 . . 1292 849 66 114,290,400 71 1915 . . 407 339 72 418,273,000 91 As is seen from this table the percentage of the renewed mortgages is very high and the . number of the loans made by the bank in the course of the last fifteen 3^ears is very low ; and the agrarian disorders brought grave loss to the property of the nobility only in 1907, the last year in which they occurred. In other words this table is proof of the crisis active in Russia in 1915, to get the better of which the bank had co help land al- ready burdened with mortgages. As for the definite results of the privileged mortgage business, repre- sented by a sum equal to 75 per cent, of the value of the mortgaged lands, which aimed at enabling the nobles to buy lands in Poland, it did not reach too liigh a figure. From 1894, the date of the first transactions of this kind, the bank has thus facilitated the passage Lo the ownership of Rus- sian nobles of 228 farms wliich pre\'iously belonged to Poles. Their total area was 533,024 deciatines and their total estimated value 32,316,921 roubles. Table VI. — Privileged Mortgage Transactions to enable the Purchase , of Land in Poland. Area bought with the bank's aid from 1894 to 1915 In the hands of the purchasers after the transaction Number of farms Area of land Estimated bought value Deciatines j Roubles Amount of loan Roubles Number of farms Area of land bought Deciatines Estimated value Roubles Amount of loan Roubles 28 560,887 36,150,031 26,971,500 92 205,255 [4,708,746 11,010,400 54 RUSSIA - CREDIT § 2. vSaLE of properties. Of the 41,827,300 roubles, which are the total sum of the loans granted by the Bank of the Nobility in 1915, a sum of 13,772,400 roubles was paid to the borrowers in the form of bank bonds. And as bank bonds of 1915 could be reaHzed at 77.7 per cent, on an average, the sum really received by the owners of the mortgaged lands was about 10,700,000 roubles or approximately 25 per cent of the total sum granted by the bank. This fall in the current race of bank bonds caused the proportion of the sum granted to that actually paid to borrowers to be less than it had been for six years. In the years from 1910 to 1915 the percentages formed by the sums paid were respectively, 38, 36, 37, 40, 39 and 26, and the percentages formed by the sums retained were therefore 62, 64, 63, 60, 61 and 74. The remainder was represented by the renewed debt to the bank of 22,489,000 roubles, and the sums retained for the extinction of foreign mortgages or other purposes, which amounted to 5,565,900 roubles. In the whole course of the bank's existence mortgages to various mort- gage credit banks have been redeemed up to the amount of 1,095,700 rou- bles. The following talkie gives a more exact idea of the bank's business fiom 1886 to 1915. Table VII. - - Redemption and Mortgage Renewal Business from 1886 to 1915. Bank Redemptions & renewals in terms of thoasands of roubles Total 1886- 1890 1891- 1896- 1895 1 1900 1900- 1905 1906- 1910 1911- 1915 1915 Bank of the Nobility .... Special office of tliat bank . Other mortgage credit banks 4,100 13,900 110,600 73,800 15,800 52,400 150,300 51,300 80,500 156,800 2,400 31,300 109,800 400 9,400 240,400 1,200 30,100 22,500 100 200 698,600 86,809 310,300 Total . . . 130,600 142,000 282,100 190,500 119,600 271,700 22,800 1,095.700 The sums intended for amortization, paid voluntarily and in advance to the bank by borrowers in 1915, reached the sum of 3,521,855 roubles. These payments emancipated from all burden of mortgage 629 properties having a total area of 106,045 deciatines, of which 62,917 remained the property of persons belonging to the hereditary nobility, while .[6,128 de- ciatines v.'ere ceded to persons otitside the nobility for the whole time for which they should remain mortgaged to the Bank of the Nobilit3\ The total sum paid in 1915 comprised 1,822,439 roubles paid by the nobles and 1,599,416 roubles paid by persons not belonging to the nobility. THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE LAND BANK FOR THE NOBILITY 55 A comparison of data for previous years with those of 191 5 gives the following table, which makes clear the large diminution of redemptions in 1915. Table VIII. — Voluntary Redemptions from 1910 to 1915.' Redanption I9IO. I9II. I9I2. 1913- I9I4. 1915- Percentage of debts redeemed Area freed from mortgages deciatines 239.144 401,529 232,917 247.334 148.334 97.043 Smns intended for redemption roubles 7,228,170 11,386,067 6,716,872 7.236,954 5,179.433 1,616,066 Sums paid by the nobility /o 0.7 O.I 0.8 0.9 0.7 Sums paid by others than nobles % 6.1 8.6 5-4 5-3 3-8 T.3 Percentage of mortgaged land emancipated Lands belongins to nobles % I.I 1.2 0.9 1.2 0.8 0-5 Lands belonging to others than nobles % 5-6 12.9 6.7 7-3 1-7 1-7 This table shows one fact which is not without interest, namely that the most important redemptions are made by persons who do not belong to the nobility. The total number of properties mortgaged to the bank which changed ownership during 1915 was 1544. Their total area was 691,983 deciatines and they were burdened wdth a total mortgage debt of 29,443,300 roubles which changed ownership with them. These properties were distributed as follows among the classes of so- ciety : Table IX. — Sale in 1915 of Properties mortgaged to the Bank of the Nobility. Purchasers 1. Hereditary nobility . . . 2. Institutions (largely the Bank of Agriculturists) . . 3. Peasants 4. Middle class 5. Traders 6. Various others . . . , . Total .... Mortgage debt burdening alienated Number Area properties of alienated — — properties deciatines roubles 373 227,620 15,062,800 31 7,802 719,200 951 88,455 6,116,100 35 ■ 4,288 270,800 39 291,970 4,156,600 115 71.848 3,117,800 ^.544 691,983 29.443.300 The data as to the alienation of properties mortgaged to the bank during the fifteen last years are also of notable interest. The alienations were as follow s : . 56. RUSSIA - CREDIT Table X. — Sale from 1901 to 1915 of Lands mortgaged to the Bank. Area of lands sold' Purchasers Institutions (the Bank of the Agri- culturists) . . . Peasants IVIiddle class .... Traders Various others . . Total. . . . 1901-1905 deciatines 16,735 477,096 89.585 434,329 471,728 1906-1910 deciatines 2,045,197 1,866,164 72,861 159,474 336,657 1911-1915 deciatines 117,058 1,168,402 78,902 162,894 472,782 Total deciatines 2,178,990 3,511,662 241,348 756,697 1,281,167 1.489,483 4,480,353 2,000,028 7,969,864 The large extent of land which in these fifteen years became the pro- perty of persons outside the nobihty, namely 7,969,864 deciatines, confirms the statements in " Material for Statistics as to the Transmission of I^ands in Russia. " The fact is therefore that nobles lose land and peasants come to possess it. Most of the land bought bj^ the credit institution is resold on privileged terms to small landless cultivators ; and if the 2,178,999 de- ciatines bought by these institutions be added to the 3,511,622 sold directly to the peasants, the enormous total is reached of 5,691,621 deciatines which have passed from the hereditary nobihty to small cultivators in the space of only fifteen years. 71,6 per cent, of these lands were sold to persons outside the nobihty. If we examine the sale of mortgaged lands during the same fifteen j^ears we find that the nobility constitute a large percentage of the purchasers, which is to sa^^ that a large although a diminishing per- centage of the lands sold remain in the possession of the nobility. In the first quinquennial period, that lasting from 1901 to 1905, 63.2 per cent, of the total number of purchasers of lands m.ortgaged to the bank belonged to the nobihty and only 14.8 per cent, to the peasantry. In the second quinquennial period, 1906 to 1910, the nobles constituted 29.6 per cent, and the peasants 61.2 per cent of the purchasers. From 1911 to 1915 the nobles constituted 46.1 per cent and the peasants 31.2 per cent, of the pur- chasers, which is to say that the nobles had regained a predominance. But if the figures for this last period be examined from year to year a marked rise in the percentage of peasant purchasers is discovered in the first year and a fall of 32.3 per cent, in 1915. Not oidj- does a large extent of mort- gaged lands pass to persons outside the nobility and especially to the pea- sants, but this extent tends to increase while the purchasing power of the hereditary nobility diminishes. At the same time a certain extent of land passes to traders, that is to say the capitalist middle class. Tliis merely confirms the perspicuous remarks of Leroy-Beauheu in his work on Russia: " The Russian nobility, no longer protected against others and themselves by the impossibility of selling to persons of a class not sheltered by the system of succession, are exposed to slow expropriation in favour of the THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE IvAND BANK FOR THE NOBIUTY 57 middle class and the peasants, who everj' year become possessed at their expense of a larger share of the soil. " On I January 1915 the total sum of arrears due to the bank by borrow- ers was 26,024,192 roubles. During 1915 the bank should have received as current mortgage revenue 43,167,391 roubles, plus 729,218 roubles in special revenues, or a total sum of 43,896,610 roubles. It recovered how- ever only 39,131,810 roubles. At the end of 1915 the total sum of ar- rears was 31,082,105 roubles. This very large sum is the best index to the crisis of which we have already spoken. Besides the sum of debts contracted on mortgages, which was 853,973,206 roubles, and that of arrears which was 31,082,155 roubles, bor- rowers were also indebted to the bank on 31 December 1915 for 133,193 roubles not bearing interest, 1,167,525 roubles which constituted special debts, and 1,563,627 roubles of deferred interest. Moreover by the law of 26 April 1906 the Bank of the Agriculturists was the debtor of the Bank of the Nobility to the extent of 166,437,668 roubles. The total number of mortgaged properties, the sale of which by public auction was decreed in 1915 because legal charges had not been paid for more than a year, was 7,364 or 26 per cent. The following table gives a more exact idea of the number of proper- ties of which the sale by public auction was decreed : Table XI. — Properties of which the Sale by Public Auction was decreed from 1901 to 1915. Payment not made May On i November 1 901 , 1902 , 1903 . 1904 . 1905 . 1906 . 1907 . 1908 . 1909 . 1910 . 1911 . 1912 . 1913 • 1914 . 1915 • Number of properties of which the sale by auction was decreed 2,284 2,401 2,680 2,632 2.975 3,815 4.359 4.359 4,072 3.486 2,611 2,576 2,625 3,080 2,521 Number of properties to be sold by auction in relation to total number of mortgaged properties /o II II 12 II 12 15 17 17 16 14 10 10 10 II 12 Number of properties of which the sale by auction was decreed 2.598 2,533 2,515 2.983 2.999 4,226 4.309 4.141 3.739 3.057 2,516 2,710 2,827 2,736 3,843 Number of properties to be sold by auction in relation to total number of mortgaged properties % 13 12 II 13 12 17 17 16 15 12 10 10 10 10 14 In whole year Properties of which tlie sale by auction was decreed 0/ /o 24 23 23 24 24 32 34 33 31 26 20 20 20 21 26 58 RUSSIA - CREDIT Tliis table shows once more that 1915 was a year of crisis ; but it is interesting to note that, in spite of what can be deduced from the number of properties of which the sale by auction was decreed, the economic de- pression of this year did not reach the gravity of the crisis of 1906- 1908. This table also shows that the position of the mortgaged properties is far from brilliant. In 7,320 out of the 7,364 cases of which we have spoken the auction could be revoked, either because the charges were paid at the last moment (4,055 cases), or because the term for payment was pro- rogued, or because the bank gave other facilities to the tardy (3,265 cases). In other words the auction could be revoked in 3,265 cases, thanks to va- rious facilities "which had a beneficient character". Only 44 properties were actually put up for auction, and of these 37 were sold while five re- mained the bank's propert}'. It is interesting here to note that, according to one of the bank's reports, " the credit of the sold properties had been exploited by the proprietors up to its final limit ; their sale was not due to influences of the moment but was the inevitable consequence of the absolute impotence of these properties to continue to enjoy credit. " The total number of properties which have thus passed to the bank became 120, of which 102 are situated in the Caucasus. § 3. The bank's funds. In the beginning of 191 5 the funds of the Bank of the Nobility were as follows : i) A capital formed by various issues of bonds of the total value of 948,700,700 roubles. 2) A capital of 74,942,097 roubles constituted by bonds issued in 1889 and not repaid. 3) A reserve capital of 12,583,618 roubles. During the year bonds for 19,337,700 roubles were issued. In all 8,807,300 roubles were repaid. At the end of the year the bank's bonds reached the total amount of 960,231,100 roubles, distributed as follows : Bonds 3.5 % 389,445,000 roubles 4 % 145,202,100 4-5 % 239,948,700 5 % 149,705,300 5 % in lots 35.930.000 Total . . . 960.231.100 During 1915 the capital formed by 1889 bonds in lots did not change (74,942,097 roubles). In 1915 the reserve capital was increased by 3,452,635 roiibles and thus the bank's reserve fund reached on 31 December the sum of 15,986,253 roubles. THE ACTIVITY OF THE STATE LAND BANK FOR THE NOBILITY 59 Besides this capital the Bank of the Nobility disposed at the end ot 1915 of real estate of the total value of 1,311,800 roubles, plus other and va- rious assets amounting to 17,318,586 roubles, and also of a special com- memorative capital of ten million roubles. To sum up : during 1915 the Bank of the Nobilitj^ notably reduced those of its transactions on which the crisis due to the war had an unfa- vourable influence. There was an important diminution in the bank's loans, a notable diminution in its emission of bonds (89,948,800 roubles in 1913, 70,138,500 roubles in 1914 and 19,337,700 roubles in 1915) ; a fall in the current value of bonds (90.5 per cent, of their nominal value in 1913, 81 to 90 per cent, in 1914, and 75.2 to 81.625 P^'' cent, in 1915) ; an important decrease in amortization (12,490,703 roubles in 1913, 10,156,811 roubles in 1914 and 3.552,577 roubles in 1915) ; and a decrease in the extent of land mortgaged (this increased by 163,546 deciatines in 1914 and decreased by 78,330 decia- tines in 1915). On the other hand there was a very notable increase in the amount of unpaid interest. It follows on the preceding data that the bank's mortgage business tends to diminish, and that 1915 was marked by too sudden a movement in accordance wdth this general tendenc3^ It also follows that the percentage of renewed mortgages tends con- stantly to increase, and this is important. In the mass uf the business it is these renewals and the complementary mortgages which prevail. This is because in the large majority of cases loans to the nobility served not to improve their farms but to meet expenses of another kind. Thus with all the facilities granted mortgages have on the whole aggravated the condi- tion of properties. They marked very often the first stage towards liquida- tion, towards the passage of a property to the ownership of persons outside the hereditary nobility. :sOTlCEvS RELATING TO CREDIT IN VARIOUS COUNTRIES. GER^IANY. AI'-, and the increase has been accentuated during the last decade, in which the contrary phenomenon has been produced in England and Ireland. Emigrants are drawn from no particular district and from no particular class of the agricultural population but from all alike. Between 1871 and 1911 the agricultural population declined by 22 per cent. ; and between 1909 and 1911 the number of emigrants rose from 33,368 to 61,328. It is true that Scotsmen have always been attracted to remote parts of the world and successful in them ; but it is probable that something might be done to arrest the tide of their emigration if further improvements were wrought in the agrarian conditions they enjoy at home. § 3. Eegislative Reforms. a) Reforms general in scope. The conditions of Scottish farming leases in general have been mainly modified by the Agricultural Holdings (Scotland) Act of 1883, amended and completed in 1908. It was provided at the latter date that tenants, and in particular market gardeners, should have compensation for their improve- ments, and compensation for damage done by game and for " unreason- able disturbance*' due to a landlord's refusal to renew their occupancy. They received moreover the right to bequeathe the remainder of a lease and greater freedom as to their system of crops. b) Reforms having particular reference to small holdings. The grievances of crofters and small tenants were much alleviated by the Crofters' Holdings Act and the Small Eandholders Act. The former, which was passed in 1886, applied only to crofts within the crofting counties rented at no more than £30 a year. It pro^dded that a crofter might not be removed from his holding except for the breach of certain statutory re- gulations. It gave him the right to have his rent fixed fairly by a public authority ; and the right, if he gave up his holding or were removed from it, to receive compensation for his improvements and those effected b^' mem- bers of his family who had held it before him. The execution of the Act and the fixing of fair rents were entrusted to a specially constituted body, the Crofters' Commission. Experience showed that there was a demand for more small holdings and that some of those in existence were too small for the needs of their tenants. In 1897 the Congested Districts' Board was established in Scotland THE SCOTTISH LAND COURT 67 and its powers included that of forming new small holdings, either in co- operation with landlords or by bu^dng land. The Small Landholders Act was passed in 1911. This extended the provisions of the Crofters' Holdings Act so that they apply not only to the crofting counties but to all Scotland, and not only to crofters but also to all tenants of no more than 50 acres of land who pa}'- a rent of no more than £50 a year. In the matter of executive the Crofters' Commission and the Congested Districts' Board were both superseded, their powers in relation to small holdings passing to the Board of Agriculture for Scotlan'd and the Scottish Land Court. The Board of Agriculture has multifarious duties which include the pre- paration of schemes for the consistution of new holdings and the enlarge- ment of existing holdings. The action involved is taken i) by the landlord voluntarih', 2) by agreement between the landlord and the board, 3) under a compulsory order from the Scottish Land Court. The duties of the Scottish Land Court are to accept or reject : i) AppHcations from the board for such compulsory orders ; 2) Applications for the determining of the status of existing holdings and the fixing of fair rents ; 3) Apphcations relating to their other powers over existing holdings. The court consists of five members appointed by the Crown on the recom- mendation of the Secretary for Scotland. One member must be able to speak Gaelic. § 4. The Scottish Land Court in 1915. a) The Formation of New Small Holdings and the Enlargement of those already existing by order of the Court. In connection with this, a principal function of the Land Court, some sentences may be quoted from its report for 1915. " Under the Small Land- holders Act the initiation of all schemes for the constitution of new small holdings and the enlargement of existing holdings devolves upon the Board of Agriculture for Scotland. All the preliminary negotiation is carried on between the board and the proprietor concerned. The Land Court have nothing whate\'er to do with these matters. The}^ have no power to in- terfere with the selection of the land proposed to be taken, or to suggest that other land would be more suitable for the establishment of new holdings or for enlargements. Nor can they deal -with the financial or economic aspects of any of the schemes submitted for their consideration. It is competent for the board and the proprietors to agree on land schemes without calling in the assistance of the Land Court at all. It is only when parties have failed to come to an agreement that the board makes application to the Land Court ". The court issues its order if it decide, after due inquiry, to accept the board's apphcation. Such order declares : 68 GREAT BRITAIN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL " i) In respect of what land, if any, specified in the scheme, one or more holdings for new holders ma}- respectively be constiti^ted, and up to what date the power to constitute them otherwise than by agreement may be exercised ; " 2) What is the fair rent for each new holding; " 3) What land, if any, specified in the scheme is to be excluded there- from ; and " 4) Whatever else may be necessary for the purpose of making the scheme effective, and of adjusting the rights of all parties interested in or affected by the scheme. From the time the Act of 1911 come into force tmtil the end of 1915 the court authorized altogether the constitution of 693 new holdings, including 22,946 acres of arable and 4,620 acres of pasture land, and 49,577 acres of common pasture. The total rents fixed for these holdings amount to £12,430 a year, or an average of nearly £18 each. In 1915 schemes were authorized for the constitution of 197 new hold- ings ; but at the same time schemes for 32 new holdings, authorized both in this and in previous 3^ears, were abandoned, mainly in consequence of the serious liabilities incurred in connection with arbitrations. The new hold- ings in which tenants were actually registered in 1915, as the outcome of schemes authorized in this and other years, numbered 176. They were distributed as follows : No. of Holdings Area County Arable Outrun Common Pasture Total Rent ArgyU Caithness Dumfries Haddington Inverness Kirkcudbright .... Lanark Perth Ross and Cromarty . Roxburgh Sutherland 22 3 9 29 79 4 2 14 2 7 5 2 1 S Q 0 0 < a ru 2,831 I II 92 3 15 300 3 23 582 2 31 2,342 3 8 152 2 32 256 — 33 654 2 35 123 3 6 2yo I 18 99—3 < « f^ 843 3 24 50 — II 60 2 2 g 1 1 256 2 — £ s d 495 9 0 5419 0 315 0 0 1,098 10 0 589 8 0 159 0 0 80 0 0 580 10 0 40 0 0 233 5 0 57 4 0 67 I 23 92 — 20 18,266 I 16 — _ — 4,571 Total . . . 176 7,727 I 15 1,114 — — 23.093 3 16 3,703 5 I It will be seen that the largest number of new holdings were in the crofting counties. Of those in Argyll seven were on the island of Mull, and all the 256 acres of common pasture mentioned in the table were appurtenant THE SCOTTISH LAND COURT 69 to these and therefore also on the island. To the largest Mull holding 12 acres of arable land pertained, to the others 5, 4, 3 or less. The fifteen new holdings on the Argyllshire mainland were more important, their arable land var^nng from 34 to 680 acres in extent. Of the Invernesshire new holdings 75, their arable land varying in area from 16 to 100 acres, were formed on the island of South Uist. Each of the remaining four new holdinges in this county, those namely which were on the mainland, had from 14 to 88 acres of arable land. A share of common pas- ture was assigned to eah Invernessshire holding, none of them having other pasture land. The far more valuable Perthshire land lay on the estates of Bread- albane and Inchmartine and was distributed in new holdings of approximately uniform size, the arable land of each being from 39 to 55 acres in area. We should notice finally the 29 holdings formed on the estate of Eli- bank in the lowland countj^ of Haddington, probably the most fertile dis- trict in Scotland. These fall roughly into three classes, those consisting approximately of 5, 10 and 20 to 30 acres of arable land. One exceptional holding has 49 acres. Neither common nor other pasture attaches to any of them. Their proximity to Edinburgh and some less towns renders them suitable places for intensive agriculture. It will be noticed that they are .far more highly rented than any of the other new holdings. As regards the enlargement of existing holdings the lyand Court effected this between 1911 and 1916 in the case of 348 holdings, to which were added altogether 2,838 acres of arable land, 536 acres of pasture land and 27,172 acres of common pasture. Schemes were authorized in 1915 for the enlargement of 61 holdings, all of which lay in the crofting counties where the evil of holdings economically too small exists as it does not elsewhere in Scotland. The following table gives details as to the enlargements thus authorized : Number of Enlarge- ments Extent County Arable or Old Arable Pasture Common Pasture Total Rent Argyll Caithness Inverness Orkney Ross and Cromarty . I 6 21 II 22 S 1 J y 0 0 65 5 0 40 9 6 53 2 0 Total . . . 61 609 — 26 140 3 37 10,888 208 9 6 Twenty-one schemes for the enlargement of holdings in Argyll, Inver- ness and Ross and Cromarty, authorized in 1915 and previous years, were 70 GREAT BRITAIN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL withdrawn in 1915 ; and land was actually assigned to enlarge only 12 holdings, one in Caithness and the others in Argyll. The activity of the Land Court in enlarging existing holdings may fairly be summed up as modifying the too great subdivision of land in the croft- ing counties. b) Registration of New Holdings and of Enlargements of Holdings formed by Agreement. It is a function of the Land Court to register the tenants selected by a landlord for the new holdings he forms, on land which has previously been otherwise occupied. Six such new holdings were registered in 1915, one in Argyllshire, the others in the south west and outside the crofting counties : Countv Number of Holdings Arable Outrun ArgyU . Ayr . . Wigtown Acres Roods Poles 38 3 4 31 — 29 126 3 2 196 35 Acres Roods Poles 49 — 16 49 — — The Act of 1911 prohibits a landlord from reletting a small holding otherwise than as such, except with the consent of the Board of Agricul- ture. If the landlord be unwilling to pay the compensation for improve- ments due to an outgoing tenant it is usual for liim to find a new tenant who will pay the outgoing tenant the value of such improvements and who is registered by the Land Court as a landholder. Twenty-seven new tenants were so registered in 1915. In thirteen cases the Land Court registered enlargements of existing holdings effected by landlords by agreement. These were as follows. THE SCOTTISH LAND COURT 7^ Number of Existing Holdings Extent of Enlargement County Arable Outrun Township Pasture Aberdeen Argyll Caithness Dumbarton Inverness Ross and Cromarty . . . I I 4 I 2 4 Acres Roods Poles 12 82 — 27 2 16 I 3 — Arces Roods Poles 12 2 38 6 I 37 3 I 4 Acres 3,000 13 49 3 16 22 I 39 3,000 c) Modification of Rents. The work of the I^and Court in coniiection with rents falls under two heads, that concerned with the crofters, called landholders by the Act -of 1911, and that concerned with the statutory small tenants. The rents of the former had within the crofting counties been dealt with before 1911 by the Crofters' Commission, but rents fixed by the commission are liable to revision at the end of everj^ seven years. The following table summarizes the Land Court's revision of rents in 1915, such revision being, as will be seen, favourable to the crofter rather than the landlord : County Nxunber of Holdings Old Rent First Fair Rent Reduction by Second Fair Rent Fair Rent in 1915 Perceotage of Reduction Argyll Caithness .... Inverness .... Ross and Cromarty Shetland Sutherland. . . . 38 170 193 136 49 8 £ s d 398 8 0 1,794 0 5 1.571 3 6 1,018 15 10 305 8 0 27 17 11 £ s d 252 2 0 1,274 2 0 1,09-1 17 5 835 I 7 222 6 8 32 16 0 & s d 201 13 0 2190 £ X d 214 9 0 1,003 8 0 871 12 8 695 8 8 186 12 0 26 6 0 14-934 21.246 20.389 16.722 16.071 19.817 594 5.115 13 8 3.7" 5 8 223 2 0 2,997 16 4 19.224 72 GREAT BRITAIN - AGRICULTURAIv ECONOMY IN GENERAL In 430 cases the Land Court fixed the fair rent to be paid for crofts with which the Crofters' Commission had not dealt, and in a considerable number of these cases arrears of rent were cancelled. County cc fl n P 0 s K % 0 Old Rent Total Amount Amount \ Z^ ordered to be ^^ Aberdeen .... Arg>-ll Bute Caithness .... Dumbarton . . . Elgin Forfar Inverness .... Kincardine. . . . Orkney Perth Ross and Cromarty Shetland Total . . . 13 5 152 I 6 2 14 I 8 2 123 82 £ s d 339 2 8 59 16 6 135 12 4 1,385 13 7 10 o o 41 o o 34 o o 94 19 3 29 12 o 57 4 o 34 13 7 1.050 2 5 423 5 8V2 430 3,695 2 oVa 209 I 38 15 81 3 1,096 15 6 o 27 5 16 5 79 I 12 10 46 18 24 10 794 18 o 314 19 38.357 35-227 40.162 20.850 40.000 33-53'3 52.205 16.756 57-77° 18.006 29-352 24-303 24.609 2,748 25-630 22 7 o 685 18 o 51 8 6 80 7 3 22 16 3 20 o o 1,370 I 7 110 10 8 2,363 9 3 347 10 6 33 19 o 20 o o 574 10 8 45 9 o 1,041 9 2 100 49.392 61.108 57-753 100 58.065 58.886 55-935 Thus total rents were reduced by more than a quarter, and more than half the aggregate sum of arrears was cancelled. The reductions of rent effected in the case of statutory small tenants were somewhat less drastic, existing conditions under this form of tenure being on the whole more equi- table. The following table gives details as to the 243 holdings of statutory small tenants for which the Land Court fixed rents in 1915 : THE SCOTTISH I,AND COURT 1?> County Number of Holdings Old Rent New Rent Percentage of Deduction Aberdeen. Argyll Caithness Dumbarton Dumfries Elgin. Fife 95 3 58 I 2 8 2 4 8 3 4 I 3 I 27 23 £ s d 2,706 9 I 26 0 0 598 2 2 35 0 0 43 0 0 134 I 0 61 00 76 17 0 237 10 7 54 5 0 280 10 0 330 66 0 0 no 00 643 12 II 173 8 0 £ s d 2,127 16 0 19 18 0 514 8 0 30 0-0 33 10 0 96 0 0 52 8 0 62 I 0 178 15 0 43 15 0 234 0 0 I 13 0 50 10 0 85 0 0 530 13 8 134 3 0 21.362 23.461 13-995 14.285 22.093 28.384 14.098 19.258 24.746 19-354 16.577 47.619 23.484 22.727 17-550 22.635 Inverness Klincardine Kirkcudbright lyanark Orkney Perth Renfrew Ross and Cromariy . . . Shetland Total . . . 243 5,248 18 9 4,194 10 0 20.087 It should be noted that the L,and Court has no power to cancel any arrears of rent in the case of statutory small tenants as it has in that of crof- ters. Kven as regards the latter it may not deal with any arrears of a rent fixed as a fair rent either by itself or by the Crofters' Commission. d) Fixing Amount of Compensation due to outgoing tenants. In this connection there is another limitation of the competency of the lyand Court. It can fix the amount of compensation due by a landlord for permanent improvements to the crofter who renounces his tenancy, but the sum thus due to a statutory small tenant in the same circumstances is fixed by an arbiter. In 1915 the court made 28 awards as to compensation to landholders : 74 GREAT BRITAIN" - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IX GENERAL County Number of Landholders for whom Compensation was fixed Amount claimed by Landholders Amount awarded by Land Court 3 13 3 (I) 8 I & s d 498 5 0 1,952 2 II 343 16 9 802 9 10(1) 65 0 0 £ s d 124 10 0 955 10 0 123 0 0 490 0 0 27 0 0 Ross or Cromarty Sutherland Total . . . 28 3,661 14 6 1,720 0 0 (i) In two cases the amounts clained were not stated. e) Grants of Leave to assign Holdings. The Crofters' Act of 1886 forbade that a crofter should "execute any deed purporting to assign his tenancy' ". This created a hardship for crof- ters disabled by age or infirmity ; and the Act of 1911 therefore ruled that a landholder whom illness, old age or infirmity had rendered unfit for work might apply to the I,and Court for leave to assign his holding to a member 01 his family, or any person who would, failing nearer heirs, succeed him if he died intestate. In 1914 the court granted leave to assign their holdings to sixt}' appli- cants in the crofting counties and none outside them. /) Effects of the War. The War affected the work of the Land Court in several ways. In the first place the numbers of its staft' were considerably reduced. In the second place the extraordinary response made by Scotland to the call for recruits for the army and the naw caused the absence of the large majority of the younger crofters and statutory small tenants. The case may be instanced of 224 acres of the farm of Aignish on the Lewis, on which are thirty-two holdings : from these 53 men went to join the colours. The natural result of volunteering on this scale was a great reduc- tion in the number of applications which came before the Land Court. The numbers of the landlords and factors and of the law agents they employ — of all those \\dth whom the Land Court usually does business — were pro- portionately reduced. Another cause for a lessening of the court's business was the deflection of pubUc money from agrarian objects to others more directly connected with the war. The reduction of parliamentary grants tended to reduce the activities of the Board of Agriculture in the matter of promoting schemes for the formation of new holdings and enlargement of existing hokUngs, and thus to reduce the number of these schemes which came before the Land Court. JAPAN. INTERIOR COLONIZATION AND THE PROGRESS OF AGRICULTURE IN KOREA. OFFICIAIv SOURCE : Annual report on reforms and Progress in Chosen (Korea) 1914-1915, compiled by the Goveniment-General of Chosen, Keijo (Seoul), July igi6. The question of interior colonization in Korea has already been studied in this Review (i), and we wiU therefore here merel}^ complete, with the help of the most recent official data, the information already given. § I. Agricultural Credit, Agriculture is the principal occupation of Korea and employs 80 per cent, of the population. Agricultural products have a total value of nearly 300,000,000 yen (2) and account for more than 80 per cent, of the total export, trade. The problem of agricultural credit is therefore urgent. Such credit is afforded a) by the Agricultural and Industrial Banks, b) by the People's Bank Associations, and c) by the Oriental Development Company. The two former are organized under regulations dating, respectively, from 1906 and 1907. Owing to changes in the general position these regu- lations were modified in 1914. a) AgricuUural and Industrial Banks. — The new regulations recognize that the'^" banks can discharge, as previously, the functions of ordinary banks, in addition to their main functions ; but require them gradually to confine their activity to the latter, by extending banking facilities more and more to agricultural and industrial enterprises in that they furnish funds to these on easier terms. The banks are especially authorized to deal with tem- porary loans, exchange bills, documentary bills and warrants for products obtained in the peninsida. In order to acquire funds for these operations the banks are however authorized to make temporary loans and receive ordin- ary deposits, apart from the funds provided for long-term loans for agricul- tural and industrial undertakings. They are also authorized to enter into close connection with the banking department of the Oriental Development Company, so that the latter may furnish larger working funds to them. To a certain extent they can act as the company's agents, much as People's Bank Associations act as agents to themselves. The Agricultural and (i) See Nos. 7,8 and y, year 1914, Interior Colonization in Japan. (2) I yen = 2. 0664 .s at par. 76 JAPAN - AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Industrial Banks were formerlj' authorized to issue debentures to the amount of five times their paid-up capital ; but the new regulations seek to safeguard their stability by imposisng greater restrictions on the issue of debentures, and the maximum amount of these ma}^ not now exceed the amount of long-term loans repayable in annual instalments, and they must be concelled as the loans are repaid. Thanks to the new regulations and the gradual progress of industry and agriculture the Agricultural and Industrial Banks have been able to furnish much larger funds to the enterprises they can support. Their business in 1914 was however less good than in 1913 owing to the financial lull caused by the European war and the depression in the prices for rice. The number of branch offices of the six banks passed from 36 in 1913 to 37 in 1914, the amount of the paid-up capital from 1,467,945 yen to 1,469,890 yen, the amount of debentures issued from 2,990,000 yen to 2,910,000 yen, the re- serve fund from 479,339 yen to 486,682 yen, the balance of the deposits from 4,599,926 3^en to 4,718,821 yen, the balance of the loans from 6,280,105 yen to 8,028,558 yen, the balance of discounted bills from 5,303,517 yen to 3,526,090 yen and the profits from 215,649 yen to 125,409 yen. The agricultural methods of the Korean people are rather elementary and loans for agricultural or industrial objects did not at first reach any con- siderable amount. Of late however, and especially since the annexation of Korea by Japan, an increasing demand has arisen for funds for irriga- tion, works of civil engineering and other agricultural enterprises ; and loans made for these purposes have therefore reached a considerable sum, as is shown by the following table : Year Ii:hing relevant to a contract of the sort being taken into consideration, is indicated by the following for- mula : , , 600-60 (I) = 270 crowns. Take another hN'pothesis. Suppose that the holding in question, while the form of its tenure is still that of free proprietorship, has an area of only 40 dunum (3). The revenue to be derived by the aga is then repre- sented as follows : 400-40 (2) = 180 crowns. 2 These formulae show that the revenue derived by the aga from ciflic land having an area of 60 dunum is equal to that of a holding of only 40 dunum which he holds in free ownership. The ratio which should obtain between an aga'a share and the whole area of any ciflic holding subjected to the proposed division, is therefore expressed as follows: 40 : 60 = 2 : 3. (i) 60 dunum = 136.90005 acres. {2) I crown of gold = 10.08096 d. at par. (3) 40 dunum = 91. 2667 acres. XOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 83 That is to say two thirds. It is therefore permissible to claim that the aga ought to be satisfied even if after the proposed division of his ciflic land not the whole two thirds of its area, to which he would have a right according to the preceding calculation, but a slightly less extent were as- signed to him, say three fiths of the total area. The author states that the aga would be inclined to relinquish this small part of his rights in conside- ration of the special advantage he would derive from the division of his ciflic land. He would indeed be enabled by the division, which would make him a free proprietor, to emanicipate himself from the numerous annoj'ances and difficulties which are often enough caused by the kmeti of Bosnia and Herzegovina. To give an idea of them it is enough to say that a kmet who is ill dis- posed to his aga can wrong him in a very simple way, b^^ neglecting, for instance, the ordinary tilth of a larger or smaller part of the ciflic holding and employing it as pastureland for the raising of live stock. The cause of the loss which the aga thereby incurs is the fact that the latter has the right to take one sixth of the crops of the land entrusted to his kmet but has no part what- ever in the profits of land left as pasturage or in the profits of keeping live stock. And this is not the only method by which the kmet can cause annoy- ance. In such cases the law certainly gives the right to take out a penal ac- tion against the kmet but in practice this expedient is too little efficacious for the aga to count upon its success. It is clear therefore that the author is logically justified in prophesying that the agas will receive the new agra- rian reform he proposes with favour. Another of his statements is justified also, the statement that every aga ought to be inclined to agree to the assignment to himself in free proprietor- ship of only three fifths of the total area of his ciflic land, instead of the two thirds to which he would actually have a right when the aforesaid division of the holding was made. We must add that an identical double prophecy can be made in the case of the kmeti. To prove this statement the author employs an argument like that used in the case of the agas. We have already had occasion to note that the kmet has a right to two thirds of the value of the products of a ciflic holding, after the amount of the tithe has been subtracted from such value. The profits accruing to the kmet from a holding of 60 dunum are therefore expressed by the following formula : (3) (600-60) 2/3 = 360 crowns. Let us now suppose that a holding of only 40 dunum is ceded to the kmet in full ownersliip The profits he will derive from it are expressed by the following formula : (4) (400-40) X 360 crowns. In other words, it may be deduced from formulae (3) and (4) that when a given holding is divided two thirds of its total area will accrue to the kmet. 84 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAI, ECONOMY IN GENERAL, Therefore an aga will have, equally with his kmet, a right to two thirds of the ciflic holding on which both have claims. Having estabhshed this cir- cumstance the author points out that the kmet might very well also, like the aga, content himself with three fifths of the holding instead of the two thirds which would fall to him in the manner described. The small loss he would thus suffer would be outweighed by a special advantage. For before the exemplified division of the ciflic holding of 60 dunum he would be obliged to bear the expense of cultivating land of that extent ; whereas after such division he would, as has already been explained, have a free property of an area of only 40 dunum and the costs of his fanning would be proportionately diminished. After all that h?s been said it is easy to understand that the author has been able to establish, on the basis of an exact principle, the following for- mula which gives the desired key to a just division of ciflic lands between the aga and the kmeti 'U -+- 'U = I V5 (!)• This formula signifies, translated into ordinary language : i) that the area which either an aga or a kmet would have the right to hold in free proprietorship is represented by three fifths of the total area of a ciflic holding ; 2) that this holding should therefore receive an addition equal to one fifth of its area. The question therefore arises — Who should furnish at the time of the division of a ciflic holding this missing fifth which is necessary to equity ? The author answers unhesitatingly that it is the part of the State to in- tervene and provide the needed territorj^ He affirms that such interven- tion is possible because the State posseses in Bosnia and Herzegovina large extents of land which now yield hardly any profit. Such are indeed the 571,635 hectares (2) which are used only for the pasturage of live stoci: and the other 212,700 hectares which are overgrown with woods and bush- es. The State is therefore fully able to provide the 94,346 hectares which would, according to the author, allow the proposed agrarian reform to be applied without injury to any private interests. The author adds that the reform should include the preservation of the emanicipated properties from too great subdivision, especially those of them which would fall to agas. The better to attain this end the agas and the kmeti should be encouraged to accept this second part of the projected reform by the grant of an amount of land somewhat in excess of that to which they really would have right. Therefore the author proposes that (i) It should be noted that the author in establishing this formula has not taken intoaccotmt: a) that the value of the products belonging to the aga is a net value while that accruing to the kmet is a gross value ; b) that in speaking of the division of the products between the aga and the kmet the re- ference is to the principal products of the soil whereas the secondary products (of the vegetable garden, orchard etc), and the profits derived from stock raising accrue to the kmet only. (2) 1 hectare = 2.47 acres. NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL 8$ • the State should cede not only the 94,346 hectares already mentioned but double that area, nameh 188,692 hectares, the value of which may be computed, according to the prices usually paid to the State by settlers acquiring land, as 2,075,612 crowns. The author then proposes that the appHcation of the projected reform should not be obligatory but that the agas and the kmeti should have full liberty to accept or reject it. It is however his opinion that both will re- ceive it favourably, for the simple reason that the proposed division of lands will be useful to both. This result would, he says, be reached f ai more easily if the State declared itself ready to cede a part of its property to the agas and the kmeti on condition these were in their turn ready to accept the applica- tion of the agrarian reform in question at a given moment, that is to say be- fore the special laws called Baltalik and Mezzas, which have reference to the cession of State lands to the communes, were applied. This impulse given by the State would. Dr. Feifalik afhrnis, contribute to an unhesitating acceptance on the part of the agas and the kmeti of a reform which would be of general service. It would, as has already been said, be optional. But while Dr. Feifalik maintains the usefulness of leaving to the agas and the kmeti full liberty to accept or reject the proposed reform, he is of opinion that there are exceptional cases in wliich the State would have to compel the division of the lands on the lines indicated, even hav- ing recourse sometimes to measures of force. These cases are the following : i) When a minority among the kmeti depending on a single aga op- posed their majority who wished to accept the aforesaid proposed agrarian reform. The author maintains that in this case the State should impose the aforesaid reform on all the dissenting kmeti, especially if the lands culti- vated by the latter were so situated in relation to those cultivated by the kmeti favouring the reform that they would be an obstacle to its application. It is the author's opinion that in the case of an obstinate opposition on the part of these dissenting kmeti the State should compel them to migrate to other localities. 2) The second exceptional case would occur in the districts of Bos- nia and Herzegovina within the war zone. The author advises that the State should reserve the right within the war zone to render the applica- tion of the agrarian reform obligatory where there seemed to be a^need for it and also to have recourse to coercive measures where, for example, there was question of expropriation or other such action. Proceeding to consider the territorial distribution of the State's landed property the author remarks that the State domain, although in general rich in land, is insufficient in the eight districts which border the Save. Where these districts are concerned he proposes to compel the agas to cede the lands thej^ possess in exchange for others lying in regions where the landed property of the domain is more considerable or even excessive. Should the agas in question oppose this plan the author proposes simply that the law relative to the repurchase of lands should be apphed to these districts. 86 NOTICES RELATING TO AGRICULTURAL ECONOMY IN GENERAL Before concluding we must state that Dr. Feif alik's ideas and the reform he proposes, as resumed by us, refer especially to Bosnia. Since in Her- zegovina the jurisdictor}^ relations between agas and kmeti are slightly different from what they are in Bosnia, the author has wished to make the former province the subject of a special study in which he hopes to present his conclusions regarding it. AUSTRIA. AGRAR-COMPASS. JAHR- UND ADRESSBUCH DER OSTERREICHISCHEN LAND- WIRTSCHAFT (Agrar-Compass. Year-book and Directory of Austrian Agriculture) Pub- lished by Rudolf Hanel, Vienna, 1916, pp. 1788. There were already books like this one in Austria concerned with industry and commerce. The present volume fills a gap and supplies a need much felt not only by agriculturists but also by all interested in business, and is a po- tent aid to the general economy of the country. For in spite of the great pro- gress made by co-operation and the existence of other noteworthy insti- tutions, Austria has lacked the means by which a complete idea of the mar- ket in a broad sense can be formed, and the connection between consumers and producers has had a casual rather than a systematic character. This has been largely due to the fact that agriculture has lacked the expedient which had long and successfully served industry. The editors of Agrar Compass have made it their aim to understand and explain agricultural production in all its branches from the point of view of its capacity to enter into the move- ment of commerce. The new directory deals especially with those agri- culturists who bring onto the market a quantity of products considerable from the commercial point of view. The war prevented this collection of addresses from comprising those of the agriculturists of Galicia and Bukovina, in which countries ownership has undergone many and im- portant changes and modifications. The book gives the names and addresses of the owners of farms and forest holdings, and of their secondary establishments when these surpass an area fixed in accordance with the crops grown ; of the dairy farms — those producing milk and cheese and collective dairies — ; of agricultural unions for purchase, sale and stock-breeding and other co-operative societies and corporations ; of distilleries, mills, industries for working with wood, sugar refineries, factories for making preserves and substitutes for coffee, and tobacco industries. Pages 1221 to 1268 are occupied by general statistics giving the data as to the agricultural, economic and forestal position in each State, that is with regard to agriculture, forestal economy, stock-breeding, the indus- tries for alcoholic drinks, mills, and the treatment and preparation of wood, sugar, preserves, coffee substitiites, and tobacco. RUGGERI ALFREDO, gerente responsabile (c) Publications of the Bureau of Agricultural Intelligence and Plant Diseases. 1. i,E Service de Protectidn contre les maladies des plantes et les iNSECTEs NtJisiBLES DANS LES DiVERS PAYS (The Present Organization of the Services for the Control of Plant Diseases and Insect Pests in the Different Countries). (1914, 350 pages, 4to) Frs. 4.00 a. PRODUCTION ET CONSOMMAIION DES EnGRAIS CHIMIQUBS DANS LE MONDB (Production and Consumption of Chemical Manures in the World). (Second Edition, 1914, 162 pages, 5 diagrams, 2 maps, i6mo) 3.50 3. I,A LUTTE CONTRE LES SAUTERELLES DANS LES DIVERS PAYS(The Campaign against l,ocusts in Various Regions) (1916, 188 pages, i6mo) t 3.50 {d) Publications of the Bureau of Economic and Social Intelligence, r; I<*activit6 de l'Institdt International d'Agriculture dans le Do- MAINE DE LA COOPERATION, DE L'ASSURANCE ET DU Cr^IT AGRICOLES (The Work of the International Institute of Agriculture in the Field of Agricultural Co-operation, Insurance and Credit). (In French, German and Italian). (1912, 34 pages, i6mo) 1 0.50 2. Monographs on Agricultural Co-operation in Various Countries, Vol. I. (191 1, 451 pages, i6mo). (In English and French) ■ 3.50 Do. Vol. II. (1915, 213 pages i6mo). (In English and French) ... « 3.50 3. An Outline of the Ectropean Co-operative Credit Systems (Second Edition, 1913, 72 pages, i6mo) 1 0.50 4. 1,'Organisation de la statistique de la cooperation agricole dans QUELQUES pays (The Organization of the Statistics of Agricultural Co- operation in Certain Countries). (191 1, 163 pages, Svo) 1.50 5. I<'assurance-gr£le dans QUELQUES PAYS ET 3ES PROBLi^MES (Insurance against Hail in Some Countries and its Problems). (1911, no pages, Svo) . , 1 1.50 6 agricultural Credit and Co-operation in Italy: Short Guide to Rural Co-OPERATION IN ITALY (in English, 35 pages and in Italian, 34 pages, i6mo) • 0.25 (e) Other publications. 1 . 1,'lNSTiTUT International d'Agriculture, son organisation, son ACTiviifi, SESRfesuLTATS (The International Institute of Agriculture, its Organization, Activity, andResults). (1914,31 pages, in English, French and Italian; illustr.) Frs. i — 2 . I«otns-Dop : I^e Present et l'Avenir de l'Institut International d'Agriculture (Conference) (Present and Future of the International Institute of Agriculture) (Address). (191 2, 60 pages, i6mo) * i — 3. Santiago Aldunate: El Instituto Internacional de AGRiCULTURA y 9U IMPORTANCIA PARA LA AmEriCA lyATINA, EN ESPECIAL PARA CHILE (Con- ferencia) (The International Institute of Agriculture and its Importance for Latin America, especially for Chile). (1913, 30 pages, i6mo) (Address). ... • 1 — II. Publications not for Sale. I. Conference Internationale de 1905 potiR la crEation d'un Institut International d'Agriculture (International Conference of 1905 for the Foimdation of an Inter- national Institute of Agriculture), (1905, 254 pages, 4to). a. AcTES DES AssemblEes GEnErales DES annEes 1908, 1909, 191 1, 1913 (Proceedings of the General Assemblies of 1908, 1909, 191 1 and 1913). (Four volumes, 8vo., one i6mo). 3. ProcEs-verbaux du ComiiE Permanent des annEes 1908, 1909, 1910, 1911, 1912, 1913 (Proc^-verbaux of the Permanent Committee, 1908, 1909, i yio, 1911, 1912, 1913, 191 4 and 1915). (Five volumes, 8vo., and two i6mo). 4. Rapports et Etudes du Bureau de la Statistique GEnErale (Reports and Studies of the Bureau of General Statistics). (191 1, 260 pages, 8vo). 5. The Science and Practice of Farming during 1910 in Great Britain. (646 pages, i6mo). 6. Etude sur les recensements de la population agricole, les salaires de la main- D'CEUVRE RURALE ET LES COURANTS D'EmIGRATION D.'VNS LES DIFFERENTS ETATS ( StUdy on the Census Returns of the Agricultural Population, the Wages of Rural I,abour, and the Currents of Emigration in the Several Countries). (1912, 150 pages, Svo). NOTE, (i) All subscriptions and remittances for the Institute's publications should be made either directly to the International Institute of Agriculture, Rome, or to the principal booksellers. For Great Britain and Ireland, subscriptions to the Bulletins x, 2, 3 and remittances foi the Year Books are also received at the Board of Agriculture and Fisheries, 4 Whitehall Place, I^ondon. S. W. (2) The prices quoted include packing and carriage. All our publications are despatched on receipt of postal order or international reply coupons. (3) Despatch is made with every care and punctuality, but unregistered volomes travel at consignee's risk. (4) To avoid miscarriage, for which the Institute does not hold itself responsible, an adH- tlonal amount of 25 centimes for registration should be sent with each order. (5) In case of change of address, the subscriber is requestedto notify the Publishing Bureau of ths Institute, forwarding address label. New York Botanical Garden Librar 3 5185 00260 9772