UNIVERSITY OF

ILLINOIS LIBRARY

AT URBANA-CHAMPAIGN

BOOKSTACKS

,

THE HECKMAN BINDERY, INC. North Manchester, Indiana

JUST FONT SLOT TITLE

H CC 1W 22

H CC 1W

H CC

H CC

2 1 LTY WUixXING 19 PAPER

8 1983-84 7 NO. 991-1

330

B385<"CV"> no. 991-1009

<IMPRINT> U. of ILL LIBRARY URBANA

BINDING COPY

PERIODICAL: CUSTOM STANDARD ECONOMY THESIS BOOK: D CUSTOM D MUSIC ECONOMY AUTH. 1ST

RUBOR TITLE ID. SAMPLE

NO. VOLS. THIS TITLE

LEAD ATTACH.

ACCOUNT LIBRARY NEW

672 001

ACCOUNT NAME

7 OF ILLINOIS

ACCOUNT INTERNAL ID

FOIL MATERIAL

WHI

'912400

NOTES

■A

COLLATING

35

ADDITIONAL INSTRUCTIONS

BINDING WHEEL

FREQUENCY

ISSN.

SYS. ID.

1 3

:76

Dept=STX4 Lot=201 Item- 1CR2ST3CR MARK BY # B4 9

SEP. SHEETS

PTS. BD PAPER

INSERT MAT.

PRODUCT TYPE

HEIGH I

TAPE STUBS

SPECIAL PREP.

LEAF ATTACH,

ACCOUNT LOT NO.

201

ACCOUNT PIECE NO.

121

VOL THIS

2?

COVER SIZE

X

HV

41

001247943

FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 993

JHE LIBRARY OF. THE

JAN 1 1

UNIVERSITY

AT URBAN A- J1>

The Nonlinear Consumption Function: Could Reagan Be Right?

Ralph D. Husby

College of Commerce and Business Administration Bureau of Economic and Business Research University of liiinois, Uroana-Cnarnpaign

BEBR

FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 993

College of Commerce and Business Administration

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

November 1983

The Nonlinear Consumption Function: Could Reagen Be Right?

Ralph D. Husby, Associate Professor Department of Economics

Digitized by the Internet Archive

in 2011 with funding from

University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign

http://www.archive.org/details/nonlinearconsump993husb

Abstract

Evidence presented twelve years ago indicated that the consumption function was nonlinear with marginal propensities to consume declining with income. In this paper, new evidence from the 1972-73 Consumer Expenditure Survey is presented which tends to confirm that the con- sumption function is indeed nonlinear. As a result, redistributions of income from higher income families to lower income families will cause aggregate spending to increase. Conversely, redistributions of income from lower to higher income families will cause aggregate saving to increase.

The Nonlinear Consumption Function: Could Reagan Be Right?

Introduction

Some years ago, one of the liveliest controversies in economics was the conflicting evidence on consumption from time series and cross section data. The latter data rather consistently indicated that the average propensity to consume declines as income increases. Studies of the time series, however, showed that the consumption function was linear about the origin, the average propensity to consume therefore being constant. The relative income, permanent income, and life cycle theories of consumption were attempts to explain the inconsistency in the two types of data. Regarding the question of the relationship between aggregate consumption and income over time, all of these theories suggest that cross section data are misleading and give us biased estimates of the average propensity to consume. As these aggregates have grown over time, the consumption propensity has remained fairly close to that predicted by a consumption function estimated from time series data.

But what happens if, at a moment of time, there is a redistribu- tion of income between income classes? Will there be short run or intermediate run impacts on aggregate spending? A consumption func- tion which reveals the relationship between aggregate spending and aggregate income over the long run may not aid us in predicting the effect of a redistribution of income. The question now becomes: At any moment of time, would high income families spend a different (presumably lower) percentage of an increment of income compared to low income families? If the consumption function Is nonlinear with

-2-

the marginal propensity to consume declining with income, then a redistribution of income from higher to lower income families would increase aggregate spending.

Reaganomics and Redistribution of Incomes The economics of the Reagan administration has given this issue greater significance. Reaganomics emphasizes the other side of this coin. If higher income families have a lower marginal propensity to spend (higher marginal propensity to save), then redistributing income in favor of high income families would result in increased saving in the aggregate, and (it is hoped) increased investment. The economic policy of the Reagan administration depends critically on this assump- tion of differential marginal propensities to consume by income class.

New Data Evidence from the 1960-61 Survey of Consumer Expenditures (Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1965) along with time series data has been pre- sented by the author (Husby, 1971) and it suggests that the consump- tion function is nonlinear and that redistributions of income would have impacts on aggregate spending and saving. Recently, data from the 1972-73 Consumer Expenditure Survey have become available. In this paper, these new data are used to retest the hypothesis that the consumption function is nonlinear.

Cross Section Estimates Using these new cross section data, a simple linear regression was run with the following result:

(1) c - 3045 + .503y, R = .977, SE = 622, D-W = .961, (293) (.023)

-3-

where c is average current consumption expenditures and y is average income after taxes (U.S. Department of Labor, 1978) for 12 income

brackets (see Table 1), the numbers in parentheses are the standard

—2 errors of the estimated coefficients, R is the adjusted percentage

of variation explained, SE stands for the standard error of the estimator, and D-W is the Durbin-Watson statistic. The latter statistic is usually meaningless for cross-section regressions, but since the data are arranged by increasing values of income, it is a test for nonlineari ty . In fact, the residuals and the Durbin-Watson statistic from (1) indicate nonlinearity , so the following specifica- tion was run:

(2) c = 1815 + .756 y - .00000812 y2, R2 = .9995, SE = 89, D-W - 1.73, (70) (.012) (.00000037)

The statistically significant coefficient for the squared income term,

—2 the improved R and standard error, and the Durbin-Watson statistic,

now being in the neighborhood of 2, all indicate that the relationship

is curvilinear rather than linear.

The Complete Model The complete model proposed in this paper is the same variation of the permanent income hypothesis that this author used in the previous study (Husby, 1971). Consumption is a nonlinear function of dispos- able income, both past and present:

(3) ct = a +blyt +b2yt_1 + b3yt_2 + ....

+ Vt +e2yt-l +Vt-2 + •••• +V

-4-

Making the distributed lag assumption (of the geometric decay type) and performing a number of algebraic manipulations, it can be shown that (3) reduces to

2

(4) ct = a + b1yfc + e^ + YC^ + (ut "Yu^).

where a = (a - ya) .

Cross section data, however, do not allow one to estimate a coef- ficient for the lagged consumption term in (4). A mixed estimation technique is therefore used whereby both time series and cross section data are utilized. Time series regressions provide an estimate for y, the coefficient of the lagged consumption term. This coefficient can then be used as prior information in a cross section regression to determine the coefficients of the other variables.

Time Series Estimates Using annual data from 1948 to 1980, we find that

(5) C = 8.87 + .903 Yd, "r2 = .998, SE = 8.60, D-W = 1.28,

(4.61) (.007)

where C is aggregate personal consumption expenditures and Yd is aggregate disposable personal income, expressed in billions of constant 1972-73 dollars (U.S. Department of Commerce, 1980 and 1981). Residual autocorrelation is indicated by the Durbin-Watson statistic. Using the same assumption as used in the discussion of the complete model, namely that consumption is a function of disposable income,

For the derivation of (4), see Husby (1971), p. 77.

-5-

both past and present, with the influence of disposable income declining systematically for past periods, yields a consumption func- tion with income and lagged consumption as the explanatory variables:

(6) C = 6.33 + .630 Yd + .313 C C (4.33) (.104) C (.119) C

¥2 = .998, SE = 7.88, D-W = 1.51.

—2 The improved figures for R , the standard error, and the Durbin-

Watson statistic in (6) all suggest that (5) is a misspecified func-

2 tion and that (6) more closely captures reality. The results of the

time series analysis are quite consistent with typical time series

results: The consumption function appears to be linear about the ori-

3 gin and to depend on both present and past values of income.

Mixed Estimation Results The time series results have yielded an estimate for y of approxi- mately 0.3. We can use this estimate as prior information to estimate

4 the coefficients of the complete model.

(7) c - 0.3c - 1291 + .5379y - .000005776y2 , R2 = .995, SE = 63.4, Z (50) (.0086)t (.000000264)t

D-W = 1.73.

2 Care must be exercised in interpreting the improvement in the

Durbin-Watson statistic since it is biased toward 2 when the lagged

dependent variable is included (see Nerlove (1966)).

3 2

Testing for nonlinearity , a regression like (6) but with Y

added as a variable was run. However, both the coefficient of the

squared terra and the lagged terra was insignificant at the 5% level.

4 The prior information used in equation (7) is an exact linear

restriction. See Goldberger (1964).

-6-

The cross section data used is for one time period only: For each family interviewed, information was gathered either for the 1972 year or the 1973 year, hut not both. Therefore, in equation (7), a proxy variable was constructed for consumption in period t-1.

Implications of the Results All of the coefficients in (7) including the coefficient for the income squared term are significant at the one percent level (2-tail t-test). We therefore rewrite the equation as

(8) c = 1291 + .538v - .00000578y2 + .3c

t ' t J t t-1

It might be well to summarize the findings to this point. It is being suggested here that the consumption function at any point in time is a nonlinear function of income. However, as incomes on average increase over time, the consumption function is shifting upward, in such a way that the relationship between aggregate consumption and aggregate income over time is linear. The fact that consumption is a function of both present and past values of income is the explanation for the function shifting upward over time.

This same conclusion was made in my earlier (1971) article. It is interesting to see just how far the function has shifted up after 12

Per capita personal consumption expenditures in 1972 dollars in- creased by 4.6% between 1971 and 1972 and by 3.2% between 1972 and 1973, an average of 3.9% (Economic Report of the President, Feb. 1983, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, 1983, p. 191). Consump- tion expenditures (c) was therefore reduced by 3.9% to arrive at the

variable c , . t-1

-7-

years. Estimating the same relationship using the 1960-61 data, the result is as follows:

(9) c - 0.3c = 362 + .630 - .00000802/

The coefficients for income and income squared are similar to (8). The value of the shift variable (constant terra), however, has increased from $362 to $890 (in constant dollars) over that 12 year period. The marginal propensities to consume, both short run (SRMPC) and long run (LRMPC) , are presented in Table 1 for the 1960-61 period and the 1972-73 period.

TABLE 1. Propensities to Consume Implied by Equations (8) and (9)

1972-73 1972-73 1960-61 1960-61 SRMPC LRMPC SRMPC LRMPC

Income

Ave.

Ave.

3 racket

Income*

Cons.*

0-3000

$ 1,636

$ 3,211

3-4000

3,347

4,172

4-5000

4,252

4,774

5-6000

5,084

5,400

6-7000

5,928

6,023

7-8000

6,715

6,501

8-10,000

7,911

7,332

10-12,000

9,491

8,284

12-15,000

11,485

9,388

15-20,000

14,541

11,065

20-25,000

18,370

13,073

> 25,000 30,461

17,290

.52 .50 .49 .48 .47 .46 .45 .43 .41 .37 .33 .19

.74 .71 .70 .68 .67 .66 .64 .61 .58 .53 .47 .27

.60 .58 .56 .55 .53 .52 .50 .48 .45 .40 .34 .14

.86 .83 .80 .79 .76 .74 .71 .69 .64 .57 .49 .20

*Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (1978), Consumers Expenditure Survey: Integrated Diary and Interview Survey Data, 1972-73, Bulletin 1992, "Total Expenditures and Income for the United States and Selected Areas," Table 1, pp. 24-35.

Interpreting the Results The low values for the marginal propensities to consume are somewhat disturbing but not unexpected. From many studies of consump- tion as well as the results of the time series regressions above, we

-8-

know that consumption on average is 90% or more of disposable income. Thus the range of long run marginal propensities from 73 to 26 percent (1972-73) and 86 to 20 percent (1960-61) appear to be downward biased. (But that is to be expected since we have ample evidence that cross section estimates of the consumption function give downward biased estimates of the marginal propensity to consume.)

On the other hand, all of the evidence in this study as well as the earlier one by this author suggests that marginal propensities to consume (save) decrease (increase) with income. A related study (Husby, 1973) based on the estimated marginal propensities from my earlier consumption paper (Husby, 1971) concluded that a negative income tax that would guarantee a family of four $4,800 annually in 1966 would cause aggregate demand to increase by 1.1% (assuming labor supply to be unaffected by the redistribution of income). The decrease in saving from the same redistribution would have been 6.3 percent of 1966 total private saving. To put it another way, a redistribution of income of the same magnitude but away from the poor and in favor of the rich would have caused savings to increase by 6.3 percent. A similar study (Moeller, 1981) suggests redistributional effects of roughly the same magnitude.

Conclusion There has been considerable publicity during the Reagan admin- istration that the revitalization of the U.S. economy depends on

As Moeller points out in his article, he finds that consumption increases by 10 to 20 percent of the amount of the redistribution while this author found the increase to be 12 to 15 percent, labor supply held constant and multiplier effects ignored.

-9-

putting more income into the hands of those who save, high income individuals. This allegation implies that the marginal propensity to save of the high income classes is greater than that of lower income classes .

Most research on the consumption function, however, has con- centrated on linear models which imply marginal propensities to con- sume that are invariant across income classes. Thus, there has been the tacit assumption on the part of economists that redistributions of income would have negligible impacts on aggregate saving and invest- ment. The evidence presented in this paper suggests that advisors to President Reagan are correct in assuming that redistributing the tax burden so as to lighten the load for high income taxpayers will cause aggregate saving to increase. Whether this increased saving will result in increased real investment in plant and equipment is another question and one that is not addressed in this paper.

-10-

References

Goldberger, Arthur S. (1964), Econometric Theory, John Wiley and Sons, New York, 258-259.

Husby, Ralph D. (February 1971), "A Nonlinear Consumption Function Estimated from Time Series and Cross Section Data," Review of Economics and Statistics 53, 76-79.

Husby, Ralph D. (March 1973), "Impact of a Negative Income Tax on Aggregate Demand and Supply," Western Economic Journal 11, 111-117.

Husby, Ralph D. (August 1974), "The Husby Consumption Analysis: Reply," Review of Economics and Statistics 56, 403.

Kuznets, Simon (1946), National Product Since 1869, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York.

Moeller, John F. (August 1981), "Consumer Expenditure Responses to Income Redistribution Programs," Review of Economics and Statistics 63, 409-21.

Nerlove, Marc and Kenneth F. Wallis (January 1966), "Use of the

Durbin-Watson Statistic in Inappropriate Situations," Econometrica 34, 235-238.

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (January 1980, November 1981), Survey of Current Business 60 and 61.

U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (February 1965), Survey of Consumer Expenditures, 1960-61, BLS Report No. 237-93, Table 1-A, 11.

U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics (1978), Consumer Expenditure Survey: Integrated Diary and Interview Survey Data, 1972-73, Bulletin 1992, "Total Expenditures and Income for the United States and Selected Areas," Table 1, 24-35.

D/161

^CKMAN

3INDERY INC.

JUN95