IM 126

14. &S:

c. i

(Wt S^LAA>W

Water Resources in Illinois: Demand, Prices, and Scarcity Rents

Viju C. Ipe and Subhash B. Bhagwat

Illinois Minerals 126

Rod R. Blagojevich, Governor

Department of Natural Resources Brent Manning, Director

ILLINOIS STATE GEOLOGICAL SURVEY William W.Shilts, Chief

Equal opportunity to participate in programs of the Illinois Department of Natural Resources (IDNR) and those funded by the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service and other agencies is available to all individuals regardless of race, sex, national origin, disability, age, religion, or other non-merit factors. If you believe you have been discriminated against, contact the funding source's civil rights office and/or the Equal Employment Opportunity Officer, IDNR, One Natural Resources Way, Springfield, Illinois 62701-1271; 217-785-0067; TTY 217-782-9175.

This information may be provided in an alternative format if required. Contact the DNR Clearing- house at 217-782-7498 for assistance.

Front Cover: The Harrison and Dever Cribs of the Chicago Water Department, active water- intake cribs in Lake Michigan that pump water landward to Chicago's Jardine Water Purification Plant. These two cribs are located in about 32 feet of water 2.5 miles offshore from North Avenue Beach (photo by Joel Dexter, May 2000).

Editorial Board

Jonathan H. Goodwin, Chair

Michael L. Barnhardt David R. Larson

B. Brandon Curry John H. McBride

Anne L. Erdmann Donald G. Mikulic

William R. Roy

NATURAL RESOURCES

Illinois State Geological Survey

LIBRARY.

Printed by the authority of the State of Illinois PRT 3291907 - .6M - 2/03 ©Printed on recycled and recyclable paper stock.

Water Resources in Illinois: Demand, Prices, and Scarcity Rents

Viju C. Ipe and Subhash B. Bhagwat

Illinois Minerals 126

Rod R. Blagojevich, Governor

Department of Natural Resources Brent Manning, Director

ILLINOIS STATE GEOLOGICAL SURVEY

William W.Shilts, Chief

615 E. Peabody Drive

Champaign, Illinois 61820-6964

217-333-4747

Home page: http://www.isgs.uiuc.edu

Digitized by the Internet Archive

in 2012 with funding from

University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign

http://archive.org/details/waterresourcesin126ipev

Contents

Abstract 1

Introduction 1

Dynamics of Water Demand 2

Available Water Resources and Supply 2

Temporal and Spatial Variability in Water Prices across Illinois 3

Economic Value, Scarcity Rents, and Prices: The Case of Chicago 6

Theory of Scarcity Rents and Pricing of Natural Resources 6

Estimate of Scarcity Rents and Efficient Prices in the Chicago Region 8

Conclusions and Policy Implications 9

References 9

Recommended Readings 10

Appendix 1 1

Tables

1 Estimates of the regional demand for water in Illinois 2

2 Average growth rates in prices of water in selected cities in Illinois, adjusted

for inflation and growth in the Consumer Price Index 4

3 Monthly water charges and prices of selected utilities across Illinois in 1997 5

4 Annual costs for water supply across Illinois in 1997 5

5 Cost of extraction and purification of water in the City of Chicago in 1997 8

6 Marginal extraction cost, scarcity rent, and efficient price for the marginal

unit of water in the City of Chicago 8

Al Counties in 11 Illinois regions 11

A2 Cost of providing water in Chicago, 1987-1997 11

A3 Costs of pumping and supplying water in the Chicago area in 1 997 11

Figures

1 Prices paid by consumers for surface water in selected cities

in Illinois, 1975-1998 3

2 Prices paid by consumers for groundwater in two Illinois cities, 1975-1998 4

3 Marginal extraction costs 7

4 Projected marginal extraction cost of water in the City of Chicago starting

in 1998 8

Abstract

Analysis of the spatial and temporal dynamics of demand, supply, and prices of water in Illinois indicates that regional scarcity of water is a real possibility within the next few decades. Alternative sources of water must be found. Current pricing policies

of municipal suppliers are based on average cost and are subject to political considerations, causing actual reve- nues of some utilities to be lower than their listed price for water. Water prices need to be based on marginal costs. When economic concepts of scarcity rent and efficient pricing were applied to water resources in Chicago, the

results showed that water drawn from Lake Michigan should have a scarcity rent of at least $1.20 per thousand gallons and an efficient price (exclud- ing distribution cost) of at least $ 1 .44 per thousand gallons. Currently, water in Chicago has a listed price of $1.07 (including distribution cost) and actual revenues of $0.69 per thousand gallons.

Introduction

Illinois seems to have enough ground- water and surface water resources to meet its current needs for drinking and for industrial, agricultural, recreational, and other purposes. Although avail- ability seems to be adequate for the state as a whole, certain regions may face water scarcity in the near future. When such scarcity arises, additional water must either be piped in from dis- tant locations, or consumption must be limited to sustainable quantities. Because there is lack of unanimity among hydrogeologists about the defi- nition of "sustainability," we have used a common sense definition in this pub- lication that regards sustainable use of a resource as possible in the long run only when withdrawal matches recharge rate.

Early signs of water scarcity have already become evident in Cook County and in the five collar counties (Lake, McHenry, Kane, DuPage, and Will) in the Chicago area where two- thirds of the state's population live. About 80 to 90% of the available water supplies in this metropolitan region are already being used, and the possibility of water scarcity is projected for some suburbs by the year 2020 (Northern Illi- nois Planning Commission 2001). An article in the Chicago Tribune (Kendall 1999) also raised the issue of potential water scarcity in Chicago and north- eastern Illinois. This area draws its water from Lake Michigan, other sur- face water bodies such as the Fox and Kankakee Rivers, wells that tap areally extensive but deeply buried bedrock aquifers, and shallower wells that tap aquifers in the near surface glacial deposits in the area. Illinois already

withdraws the maximum legally per- missible quantities of water from Lake Michigan and almost the maximum sustainable quantity from the Kankakee and Fox Rivers, the deep aquifers, and shallow wells (Winstanley and Peden 2000). Nevertheless, the population and economy of this region are expected to grow in the future, and new suburban areas continue to be developed in Cook County and adjoining counties, requir- ing additional water. As the growth con- tinues, additional demand for water can be expected for industries, power generation, and allied activities.

Although reliable estimates of available water supplies and future water demands for other parts of the state are not available, experts suggest that water scarcity is a distinct possibility in some of those regions as well. The comprehensive planning needed for water resource use and management requires good databases on the ground- water and surface water resources available for current and future pro- jected regional demand.

The use and conservation of any resource are also affected by pricing policies. Even though water is a resource in "abundance," the price charged for its use should reflect its true economic value. There have been some attempts to review the available data on the effects of water prices and family income on per capita water demand. For example, Wong (1972) investigated the water demand in 130 systems in northeastern Illinois and concluded that household water demand was relatively unaffected by price in the City of Chi- cago, but was somewhat influenced by price in the suburbs. Wong attributed this difference to the fact that Chicago is

supplied with surface water, which is rel- atively inexpensive to pump and distrib- ute, whereas the suburbs mostly depend on more expensive groundwater.

According to Wong (1972), the price elasticity of water demand is influ- enced by the absolute price level. Price elasticity indicates how demand changes with a change in price. For most goods, a decrease in price results in an increase in demand. For such goods, the price elasticity of demand is said to be -1 if a 1% decrease in price results in a 1% increase in demand, and vice versa; a number between 0 and -1 indicates inelastic demand. When industrial and commercial water uses were included and community size was not considered (i.e., when a cross sec- tional estimate was made by Wong), the price elasticity of water was deter- mined to be -0.26 to -0.82.

Stevens and Kesisoglou (1984) studied the price elasticity of water demand in Massachusetts. Their findings con- firm Wong's values of price elasticity for water demand in northeastern Illinois. Although price changes have a small effect on water demand, the effect is undeniable. The question, then, is what price would be appropriate. This ques- tion has not been studied in Illinois.

The economically grounded way to determine the appropriate price level is to match prices with the economic value of water to society, which is reflected in the "scarcity rent." Scarcity rent refers to the implicit value asso- ciated with the resource because of its expected future scarcity. This report presents the results of our attempt to measure the scarcity rent of water in northeastern Illinois.

Illinois State Geological Survey

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Dynamics of Water Demand

Water is used in all aspects of human activity, including drinking and sani- tation, irrigation, generation of elec- tricity, mineral extraction and other industrial processes, recreation, and transportation. Total water withdraw- als serve as a proxy for total demand, although private withdrawals are not recorded in most cases. Private wells are not limited to remote farmhouses; these wells also supply larger demands such as electricity generation, indus- trial production, mineral extraction, agriculture, and recreation (U.S. Geo- logical Survey 1999). In some cases, water demand (withdrawal) does not represent consumption in the usual sense. For example, the largest single water use in Illinois is for cooling at electricity generating plants, but much of this water is returned to a surface body of water a river or lake albeit at a warmer temperature. Yet this use is considered to be a demand for water in the same sense as a demand for drink- ing and other consumptive purposes because it involves costs that must be paid. Similarly, much of the wastewater that is cleaned before being discharged into a lake or stream was also previ- ously consumed for drinking or other human purposes.

Estimates of the regional demands for water in Illinois are presented in table 1 . The state is divided into 1 1 regions (appendix, table Al), and the total water withdrawal in each region is used as an estimate of the total demand. Data from year to year and region to region have been difficult to compare. Because comparable regional data on water withdrawals are available only for the years 1990 and 1992, data for those two years alone are reported in table 1. This table shows that the demand for water in the public supply systems of the state increased by about 5.9% from 1990 to 1992. Similar rates of increase in water demands occurred in all regions except in the Peoria and Central regions where demand declined.

Past trends suggest some possible future scenarios regarding demand. In areas with growing population and increasing economic activity, demand for water may be expected to increase substan- tially. Chicago and its suburbs are an example of one such area that may experience supply problems in the near future.

Available Water Resources and Supply

Ground and surface waters constitute the available water resources in Illinois. The Mississippi River on the western

border, the Ohio and Wabash Rivers on the south and east, and Lake Michigan on the northeast are the major fresh water bodies surrounding the state. The large tributaries to these major water systems in the state's interior include the Illinois, Kaskaskia, Fox, Rock, Sangamon, Big Muddy, Embar- ras, and Kankakee Rivers. There are 88,417 inland lakes, excluding Lake Michigan; total lake acreage is 301,209. The Illinois-administered acreage of Lake Michigan is 976,640 {1999 Illinois Statistical Abstract). About 80% of the inland lakes are artificially constructed. The artificial lakes include dammed streams and side channel impound- ments, strip mines, borrow pits, and excavated lakes. The natural lakes include glacial lakes found in the northeastern counties, sinkhole ponds in the southwest, and oxbow and back- water lakes along the major rivers. Most lakes provide water for drinking and cooling purposes, recreation, and fish and wildlife habitat; provide help in flood control and property value enhancement; and provide valuable ecological and aesthetic natural resources. The state has approximately 900 interior streams and 26,443 total stream miles (1999 Illinois Statistical Abstract) . As shown in table 1 , surface water accounts for the major share (94% to 95%) of the total water with- drawals in Illinois.

Table 1 Estimates of the regional demand for water in Illinois, million gallons per day.1

1990

1992

Region2

Surface water

Total

Surface water

Total

Chicago

9,727.42 (96.8)3

10,047.96

10,116.76(97.3)

10,396.12

Rockford

73.20 (37.3)

196.13

53.16(24.8)

214.77

Rock Island3

56.23 (52.4)

107.38

1,026.64(94.0)

1,092.04

Peoria

2,257.20 (95.6)

2,360.13

1,792.14(93.6)

1,914.53

Champaign

23.57 (32.5)

72.42

26.07 (32.3)

80.70

Decatur

548.10(95.8)

571.92

662.77(96.1)

689.43

Springfield

1,700.74(96.3)

1,766.53

1,659.51 (93.0)

1,784.35

Quincy

37.99 (57.8)

65.76

31.29(37.3)

83.90

East St. Louis

1,403.18(94.9)

1,479.04

1,429.46(94.3)

1,515.85

Central region

501.64(91.1)

550.49

429.01 (87.0)

493.05

Carbondale

737.48 (92.6)

796.18

757.11 (93.5)

809.76

Total4

17,066.75(94.7)

18,013.94

17,983.92(94.3)

1,9074.50

'Source: U.S. Geological Survey (1996, 1999). (Although the Illinois State Water Survey has published data on water withdrawals since 1986, its data are not comparable with recent data available from the U.S. Geological Survey.) 1 gallon = 0.1337 cubic foot. 2See appendix table A1 for list of counties in each region. 'Values in parentheses are percentages of the total withdrawals. ••Original U.S. Geological Survey data source offers no explanation for the 10-fold increase in total demand from 1990-1992.

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Illinois State Geological Survey

In addition to surface water resources, the state has an abundant supply of groundwater resources. Major aquifers underlying Illinois include ( 1 ) the satu- rated sand and gravel deposits left in the last 1.8 million years by repeated advances and retreats of continental glaciers and (2) aquifers in the bedrock beneath the glacial deposit the Penn- sylvanian-Mississippian aquifer, the Silurian dolomite aquifer, the Cam- brian-Ordovician aquifers, and the Mt. Simon aquifer (U.S. Geological Survey 1985). Large users, especially in north- eastern Illinois, generally pump water from the bedrock aquifers. Small users, such as suburban residences and farms, mostly obtain their water from aquifers in the glacial deposits and the shallow bedrock. These aquifers may offer sources of water to meet the demands from the growing popula- tion and expanding economy in some areas, but reliable estimates of reserves in the aquifers are not available.

Detailed geologic, hydrologic, mete- orologic, and engineering data on ground and surface waters are needed to determine aquifer characteristics and to develop policies for the sus- tainable use of water resources in the state. The Chicago region, with its great population density and high annual rate of industrial and munici- pal growth, is one example of a region that had local water supply problems

as early as the late 1 950s (Suter et al. 1959). These supply concerns are likely to become more severe in the future. Where available surface water supply is a concern, groundwater seems to be the alternative.

Temporal and Spatial Variability in Water Prices across Illinois

In view of the growing demand for water and concerns regarding its supply, and because price affects use, it is essential to study and understand how water prices have varied over time and from one region in Illinois to another. In order to analyze historic trends, data were collected from the major private water supply utilities and from the public water supply agencies in Illinois. Continuous, long- term data could be obtained only from the Northern Illinois Water Cor- poration, now called Illinois-American Water Company (IAWC), and from the Water Department of the City of Chi- cago. The IAWC supplies water to consumers in Pontiac and Champaign- Urbana in the Champaign region, Streator in the Peoria area, and Ster- ling in the Rockford area. Surface water is supplied to Pontiac and Streator, whereas groundwater is supplied to Champaign- Urbana in central Illinois and Sterling in northern Illinois. Other

divisions of the IAWC supply surface water to Alton, Belleville, Granite City, and East St. Louis and groundwater to Pekin. The City of Chicago Water Department gets most of its water from Lake Michigan.

As shown in figure 1, the inflation- adjusted prices of water in three com- munities supplied with surface water by IAWC and the City of Chicago decreased from 1975 through 1982 but have gen- erally increased thereafter. Prices for groundwater in Champaign showed a similar trend (fig. 2). In Sterling, prices declined from 1975 through 1982 and then increased sharply from 1982 through 1985, declining again there- after. Such sharp increases in prices could have been due to a sudden increase in fixed costs arising from con- struction and /or maintenance of plants.

Over the 24-year period from 1975 to 1998, inflation-adjusted (with 1982 to 1984 as the basis of comparison) water prices increased in all communities except Chicago, where they declined an average 1.02% per year (table 2). 1976 to 1980 was the period of greatest overall consumer price inflation in the United States, averaging 9.2% annually. Real water prices in this period declined in all cities and, in Chicago, by over 15%. After 1980, real prices generally increased in all cities, although periods of price decline occurred.

2-

1975l1976l1977l1978l1979l1980l198l'l982l1983l1984l1985l 1 9861 1987'l988' 1989'l99o'l99l' 19921 1993'l994' 19951 1996'l997' 1998

Figure 1 Prices (deflated 1982-1984 = 100) paid by consumers for surface water in selected cities in Illinois, 1975-1998. 1 cubic foot = 7.481 gallons.

Illinois State Geological Survey

Illinois Minerals l 26

1 975l1976l1977i1978l1979l1980l1981l1982l1983l1984l1985l1986l1987l1988l1989l1990l1991l1992l1993l1994l1995l1996l1997l1 99 Figure 2 Prices (deflated 1982-1984= 100) paid by consumers for groundwater in two Illinois cities, 1975-1998.

The magnitude of change in the Con- sumer Price Index is not necessarily the same as cost inflation for the water utilities. However, high rates of growth in the Consumer Price Index may indi- cate periods of large cost increases for utilities as well. Although no single reason can be given for the uneven price development over time, an important factor is pricing policy based on average costs instead of the economically more acceptable mar- ginal cost basis. Marginal cost is defined as the cost of adding one more unit of water supply, and prices are adjusted only after costs have increased. For example, unusually high inflation rates in the 1979 through 1981 period likely contributed to increased operating costs. Moderniza- tion and expansion might also have

been responsible for the price increase (e.g., Pontiac) from 1991 to 1998.

Regulatory delays in allowing price adjustments are common, and cost increases may be accommodated in other ways (e.g., by increasing meter charges and/or fire protection and fran- chise charges). Some cost increases may not be recognized by regulators as legiti- mate, but other cost increases may be subsidized, keeping prices below market cost. Drinking water is supplied by water systems owned and operated by com- munities or by privately owned but reg- ulated monopolies. Regulated monop- olies enjoy a competition-free market within their designated geographic area, but their prices are subject to approval by a civic body consisting of appointed or elected citizens. Regulated monopo- lies are permitted a certain return on

approved investments. In general, the prices charged by the utilities are strongly influenced by forces other than the market. When setting prices, regulatory bodies generally are guided by the average costs incurred by the utilities instead of the marginal costs.

Customers generally pay fixed monthly charges for the facilities needed to bring water to the place of use and meter its usage. A separate fixed charge for fire protection ser- vices is also paid by customers. The portion of customer monthly pay- ments for the amount of water used varies. Across Illinois, charges in all three categories vary widely, depend- ing on district (table 3). Customers in the City of Chicago pay the lowest fixed charges as well as the lowest price for water usage.

Table 2 Average growth rates (percentage per year) in prices of water (dollars per 1 ,000 cubic feet) in selected cities in Illinois, adjusted for inflation (1982-1984 = 100) and growth in the Consumer Price Index (CPI).

Growth rate

CPI

Champaign

Sterling

Pontiac

Streator

Chicago

1976-1998

4.82

0.64

2.67

3.59

3.07

-1.02

1976-1980

9.23

-2.78

-6.14

-5.04

-2.71

-15.33

1981-1985

4.84

2.07

23.99

-0.64

2.51

-3.44

1986-1990

4.13

-0.88

-4.24

4.12

5.50

1.75

1991-1998

2.56

2.85

-0.83

11.29

5.52

2.35

Illinois Minerals l 26

Illinois State Geological Survey

Table 3 Monthly water charges and prices (dollars) of selected utilities across Illinois in 1997.'

Fire protection and

Price

Water district

Meter charge

franchise charge

($/1,000gal)

Southern

10.50

1.23

2.65

Peoria

10.50

3.02

2.65

Pekin

10.50

2.40

1.82

Champaign

6.25

1.87

1.79

Streator

7.20

4.12

2.59

Sterling

7.30

3.27

1.85

Pontiac

6.60

4.99

3.01

Suburban Chicago

6.50

2.60

1.93

DuPage County

6.50

2.60

3.25

Fernway

6.50

2.60

1.75

Waycinden

6.50

2.60

2.11

Kankakee

8.00

1.02

1.83

University Park

4.50

5.75

1.29

Lincoln

5.49

2.91

3.23

Chicago

NA2

NA

1.07

Average

7.353

2.933

2.19

'Illinois Commerce Commission, Water/Sewer Section, Rates Department, December 31, 1997. 2Although meter, fire protection, and franchise charges are not available separately, their total

for a month for Chicago was $7.99. 3Without Chicago.

Many factors are responsible for this variation in water prices. The shares of industrial, commercial, and residen- tial consumption in a water utility's total sales are an important determi- nant of prices charged. Also significant are the number of customers served and the number of customers per square mile. Some costs (e.g., meters for monitoring usage) grow in pro- portion to the number of customers

served. Other costs (e.g., the pipe net- work serving each block) result in lower cost per customer as the number of customers increases. Maintenance costs also increase proportionally with the number of customers. The average cost per customer may be lower in high population density areas than in low density areas, and new connec- tions cost more than previous ones. Chicago's low fixed charges reflect

its high customer density and are based on average costs rather than marginal costs. Consumption patterns also affect price. Inner city and apart- ment dwellers, for example, generally use less water on lawns than do sub- urbanites and owners of single-family dwellings. Why spatial price variations exist is thus a question that requires a separate study to answer and is not included here.

The average costs in 1997 for two major utilities City of Chicago and IAWC were examined to identify pos- sible links between prices and cost because most water utilities base their pricing on average extraction costs (Howe et al. 1986, Moncur and Pollock 1988). Accounting methods of the two utilities differ significantly. Within IAWC itself, cost reporting details vary between Champaign, Alton, and Pekin divisions (table 4). For example, the operation and maintenance costs are included in the extraction cost in the Champaign division but not in the Alton division. In the Alton and Pekin divisions, interest payments are not reported separately. The total costs of all systems, however, are comparable. A comparison of total costs per thou- sand gallons of water sold with aver- age prices per thousand gallons in this limited sample of four companies indicates only a weak statistical cor- relation.

Table 4 Annual costs (million dollars) for water supply across Illinois in 1997.

Champaign,

Alton,

Sterling,

Belleville,

City

Streator,

Granite City,

Cost category

of Chicago

Pontiac1

East St. Louis'

Pekin'

Extraction2

36.70

10.74

NA3

0.65

Operation and maintenance

104.20

NA

9.76

NA

Depreciation

10.50

2.25

4.57

0.39

Interest

11.20

2.30

NA

NA

Other

59.20

2.94

NA

NA

Total cost

221.80

18.23

14.33

1.04

Average total cost, $/1 ,000 gal

0.55

2.234

0.86

0.30

Price, $/1,000gal

1.07

1.79

2.12

1.82

'IAWC.

2Cost of source of supply, power, and pumping.

3NA, not available separately.

"Costs exceed price per 1,000 gallons in 1997. Company officials pointed out that the rate-making procedure often results in delays in cost recovery, and some costs, for example charitable sales of water, are borne by shareholders. Longer- term aggregated accounting is needed for an accurate financial picture of the company.

Illinois State Geological Survey

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Economic Value, Scarcity Rents, and Prices: The Case of Chicago

When an existing source of water is exhausted, additional investments are required to make a new source avail- able. In general, the costs of accessing the new source are greater than the current costs because the lowest cost source is accessed first. Underpricing occurs when the increased costs from a shift to the new source over the life- time of the new source, also called "scarcity rent," is not accounted for in pricing decisions. Underpricing can occur, for example, when water util- ities base their pricing decisions on average costs and on regulatory guide- lines received from the Illinois Commerce Commission. There are also strong political incentives to hold down water prices. However, in view of concerns about the ade- quacy of future supply to meet grow- ing demands, it may be worthwhile to examine the true economic value of water, which is reflected in the scarcity rent and the efficient price consider- ing the scarcity rent.

Suppose that a water supply utility obtains its water from a source that has limited capacity or, like Chicago, has quota restrictions on the amount of water that can be pumped. Suppose also that the demand exceeds the supply. Then the utility must look for alternative sources to supply water as the currently available reserves are exhausted or the quota limitation has been reached. The utility must antici- pate higher costs for supplying water in the future. Prudent use of water resources requires that water pricing policies consider the scarcity rent. Data are sufficient to estimate scarcity rents and values for water for the Chi- cago region.

The Chicago area water supply system is an example of a utility facing the prob- lem of expected future scarcity from its current source and, hence, higher future cost. Northeastern Illinois, with the City of Chicago and the nearby sub- urbs in Cook, Will, DuPage, McHenry, Kane, and Lake Counties, could start suffering from water scarcity in the decades ahead (Injerd 2000, McConkey 2000, Northern Illinois Planning Com- mission 2001). The population in this area is expected to grow by about 25%

in the next two decades; this growing population and accompanying indus- trial growth will increase the demand for water, but, as stated earlier, the area is already near its maximum with- drawal allowance. The scarcity rent would be the cost savings that would result from postponing the need to access an alternative source or resort- ing to backstop technology (Turvey 1976). A backstop technology is an alternative high-cost technology or extraction from an alternative high-cost reserve. Depletion of current reserves and/or degradation of the quality of the current resource are possible reasons why backstop technologies are adopted. Desalination of sea water, which is more expensive today than use of conven- tional water sources, is one example of a backstop technology suitable for coastal areas. In the case of Chicago, explora- tion for and pumping of groundwater from deep aquifers or obtaining water from distant areas using extensive pipe- lines could be possible higher cost alternatives. If the new source requires additional steps for water purification, cost increases further. In addition, other potential users may be considering the new source, leading to competition in the water market.

Theory of Scarcity Rents and Pricing of Natural Resources

For the efficient use of a natural resource such as water, the price should equal the sum of the marginal cost of extraction and the scarcity rent (Howe et al. 1986, Moncur and Pollock 1988). Let Cbe the marginal extraction cost 9 and be the scarcity rent; then, the efficient price of a marginal unit of water may be represented as shown by Moncur and Pollock (1988):

P = C +

(1)

Assume that water scarcity problems will occur in T years. After T years, a higher-cost alternative source will have to be found to supplement the currently available reserves. Assume that the costs in both the periods up to and after year T— increase at an exponential rate. Let the growth rates of costs during the first (before the year T) and second periods (Tand later) be g, and g2, respectively. Letting Ct denote the extraction cost function in year t, then

Cx = Kxe

:-.','

c, =

C, = tf,e'

o</<r

t>T.

(2)

where C, is the extraction cost until year T, C, is the extraction cost after T years, and AT, and K, are constants. The postulated extraction cost curve represented by these functions is shown in figure 3.

At the end of year T, the cost curve is assumed to shift up because an alternative source of water supply or a backstop technology is more expensive. After T years, the cost curve rises at the exponential rate, gr The expected upward shift in the cost curve after Tyears should result in scarcity rents in the period before T. The magnitude of the scarcity rent then is equal to the decrease in the present value of future costs if year T can be postponed, thus postponing the use of the alternative source or backstop technology (Moncur and Pollock 1988). Given the cost functions presented in equation (2), the present value of the future stream of costs at time t, assuming that the cost function shifts at year T, is

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Illinois State Geological Survey

f v 8ll ~r(<l~t) i f v gj< r(q-t) ,

I K jg * e dq < K 2e *e dq

(3)

where r is the discount rate, and q corresponds to T, the base change of the integration. Conservation and/or an increase in efficiency of water use can postpone the year T. Now assume that the current water conservation practices result in more efficient use of water and that the supply agency does not have to shift to the higher-cost alternative at year T. The present value of the future stream of costs, then, is

Kxe *e dq.

(4)

The present value of the additional costs (C;n.) of resorting to the next higher-cost alternative and/or backstop technology is

7" 00 DC

(v g\' -r(q-t) , r gJ -r(q-t) , f g,t -r(q-t) ,

Cpv= lKle *e dq + \K-,e *e dq - \K{e *e dq

I T I

= K2e

t -r(q-t)

*e i

gJ-r(T-t)

Kxe

g\~r

(5)

The derivative of Cpv with respect to time, T, measures the present value of savings in costs from postponing the switch to the higher cost alternative by one time period. Thus, the scarcity rent, SR, is

SR

dC

PV - V SiT-rfT-t) r gJ-r(T-t)

(6)

In other words, equation (6) measures the savings in costs per unit time if the water supply agency can postpone resorting to the higher-cost alternative sources of water supply to meet the demands.

T, years

Figure 3 Marginal extraction costs.

^W

&

Illinois State Geological Survey

lllinoi

s Minerals 1 26

Estimate of Scarcity Rents and Efficient Prices in the Chicago Region

In order to estimate the scarcity rent, SR, estimates of T, g,, g,, and rare needed. Tis assumed to be 50 years based on expert assessment that the Chicago area may experience water shortages from current sources by the middle of the twenty- first century or earlier (Injerd 2000, McConkey 2000, Northern Illlinois Planning Commis- sion 2001). Extraction costs for the Chicago water system in the 1987 through 1997 period grew at an annual exponential rate of 5.0%. This rate is assumed to continue in the future. Thus, g,, and g, are both assumed to be 5.0% (table A2). At this time, neither the alternative water sources after Tnor the future costs are known. Therefore, three alternative scenarios are considered. The first scenario assumes that the cost curve shifts upward by 10% at T- 50 years. The second and third scenarios consider cases in which the cost curve shifts up by 20% and 30%, respectively, at T= 50 years. The discount rate r is assumed to be 2%.

In order to compute the current extrac- tion cost, we used the expenditures associated with source of supply, power and pumping, and purification in the 1997 financial report of the City of Chi- cago water supply system (table A3). The extraction costs in 1997 were about $0.22 per 1,000 gallons (table 5).

The future extraction costs were esti- mated on the basis of current costs, projected growth rates, and estimated upward cost shifts at T= 50 years; these costs are depicted in figure 4. Cost curve MCI represents the projected marginal extraction costs under the assumption that the cost shifts up by 10% in year T. Curves MC2 and MC3 depict the projected marginal costs when the cost curves shift up by 20% and 30%, respec- tively, at year T.

The projected marginal extraction costs, scarcity rents, and estimated efficient prices under the three hypothetical scenarios over 50 years, starting in 1998, are presented in table 6. All scenarios

Table 5 Cost of extraction and purification of water in the City of Chicago in 1997.

Expenditure (million $)

Average cost ($/1 ,000 gal)

Source of supply

Power and pumping

Purification

Total operating expenses

0.20 36.50 48.10 84.80

0.00 0.09 0.12 0.222

'Source: Department of Water, City of Chicago. 2Total does not add up due to individual rounding.

Figure 4 Projected marginal extraction cost (MC) of water in the City of Chicago starting in 1998.

Table 6 Marginal extraction cost (MC), scarcity rent (SR), and efficient price (EP) for the marginal unit of water in the City of Chicago.

T1

MC

SR1

EP1

SR2

EP2

SR3

EP3

1

$0.24

$1.20

$1.44

$1.31

$1.55

$1.42

$1.66

5

$0.30

$1.31

$1.60

$1.43

$1.72

$1.55

$1.85

10

$0.38

$1.45

$1.84

$1.59

$1.97

$1.72

$2.11

15

$0.50

$1.61

$2.11

$1.76

$2.26

$1.91

$2.41

20

$0.65

$1.79

$2.43

$1.95

$2.60

$2.12

$2.76

25

$0.84

$1.98

$2.82

$2.17

$3.00

$2.35

$3.19

30

$1.09

$2.20

$3.28

$2.40

$3.49

$2.60

$3.69

35

$1.41

$2.43

$3.84

$2.66

$4.07

$2.88

$4.29

40

$1.83

$2.69

$4.52

$2.94

$4.77

$3.19

$5.01

45

$2.37

$2.98

$5.35

$3.25

$5.62

$3.53

$5.90

50

$3.08

$3.30

$6.37

$3.60

$6.67

$3.90

$6.98

51

$0.00

$0.00

$0.00

'T, time

in years, starting in 1998.

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Illinois State Geological Survey

assume a 2% discount rate and a switch to the higher cost alternative in 50 years. Assuming a 5.0% exponential growth rate, the average extraction cost will increase from $0.24 per thousand gal- lons to $3.08 per thousand gallons in 50 years.

The results in table 6 suggest that, under scenario 1, the water reserves in the Great Lakes in 1998 would have a scarcity rent of $ 1 .20 per thousand gal- lons. Under scenarios 2 and 3, the esti- mated scarcity rents would be, respec- tively, $1.31 and $1.42 per thousand gallons. In 50 years (in 2047), the rents would rise to $3.30 per thousand gal- lons in scenario 1, $3.60 in scenario 2, and $3.90 per thousand gallons in sce- nario 3. In all three scenarios, the scar- city rents fall to zero in the 51st year because the water supply system, by assumption, shifts to the higher cost alternative in year T and then remains on the higher cost trajectory after year T. Efficient prices recoup the marginal cost as well as the scarcity rent. As shown in table 4, the total average cost per thousand gallons in Chicago in 1997 was $0.55. The marginal cost per thousand gallons in 1997 was $0.22 (table 5). Thus, the average cost was about $0.33 higher than the marginal cost to cover the costs of distribution and administration. This relationship may or may not continue in the future; marginal cost may exceed the total average cost. Therefore, future water prices should be determined by the greater of either the average or the marginal cost, plus the scarcity rent.

Scarcity rents provide an indication of the suggested price that will account for the potential scarcity of the resource in the future. A suggested price incorpo- rating this consideration then would be the sum of the average cost and the scarcity rent. In 1998, the total cost of supplying water would have been $1.78 per thousand gallons ($0.24 marginal cost + $0.34 distribution cost + $1.20 scarcity rent), assuming that distribu- tion and administration costs increased by 5.0% from 1997 to 1998. Similarly, under scenarios 2 and 3, the prices would be $1.89 and $2.00, respectively. These results indicate that the current price charged by the City of Chicago, $1.07 per thousand gallons, is sub- stantially less than the estimated effi-

cient price. Actual water sales and revenues received in 1997, according to the accounting report of the City of Chicago water system, indicate that the effective average receipts were only about $0.69 per thousand gallons. The real magnitude of the underpric- ing thus remains uncertain because of discounts for greater use, charitable activities, and the absence of any consideration of marginal cost and scarcity rents.

Conclusions and Policy Implications

This report considers the economic value of water as an essential resource in the state in relation to its growing demand, especially in the fast-growing northeastern areas. Indications of an impending water shortage in the Chi- cago area are revealed by expert opin- ions from important water research agencies in the state. The City of Chicago water system already pumps about 85 to 90% of the maximum legally allowable quantity of water from Lake Michigan and is probably approaching the limits of sustainable groundwater extraction from aquifers in the area. Because of the lack of sustainable yield estimates for the vari- ous aquifers, however, it is impossible to make definitive assessments as to when water scarcity may become a reality and what additional costs will have to be paid to secure alternative water resources. It appears certain that, as demand grows, water scarcity will eventually occur. Previous research has indicated that water demand responds to price changes, although neither strongly nor uniformly across commu- nities. Water demand is influenced also by factors such as household income. However, little research exists to deter- mine what price levels would be eco- nomically rational.

The concepts of marginal costs and scarcity rent are used in this paper to present a guideline to calculate an eco- nomically rational price level for water in the Chicago area. Data show that current prices are determined more by average costs than by marginal costs. Moreover, prices currently charged by water utilities do not account for the true value of water in the face of antic-

ipated scarcity. Political factors also have a strong influence on water pric- ing policies. Real water prices in the Illinois communities studied followed a downward trend from 1975 until 1982, which continued in Chicago through 1998. In the other studied communi- ties, real water prices generally have been increasing since 1982, although neither consistently nor uniformly among communities.

Scarcity rents provide a means to price current water supplies to account for future scarcity costs. However, relevant data for estimating scarcity rents of water resources were available only for the Chicago region. Those data strongly suggest that computed prices including scarcity rent would be much greater than the prices Chicago cur- rently charges for water. The results of the study also suggest that consideration of scarcity rents and marginal costs in the pricing of water could encourage reduced water consumption and help postpone the occurrence and/or inten- sity of the anticipated water scarcity.

References

Howe, C.W., D.R. Schurmeier, and W.D. Shaw, Jr., 1986, Innovative approaches to water allocation The potential for water markets: Water Resources Research, v. 22, p. 439-445.

Injerd, D., 2000, Lake Michigan diver- sion— Current status and future outlook: Paper presented at the Conference on Illinois Water Sup- plies: Is the Well Running Dry?, Holiday Inn Chicago City Center, July 18-20, 2000.

Kendall, R, 1999, Chicago's water world A saga told dryly: Chicago Tribune, September 26, 1999, p. 1, 4.

McConkey, S., 2000, Hindsight is 2020; A comparison of water demand pro- jections to 2020 and actual water use since 1950: Paper presented at the Conference on Illinois Water Supplies: Is the Well Running Dry?, Holiday Inn Chicago City Center, July 18-20, 2000.

Illinois State Geological Survey

Illinois Minerals 1 26

Moncur, J.E.T., and R.L. Pollock, 1988, Scarcity rents for water A valuation and pricing model: Land Economics, v. 64, no. 1, p. 62-72.

Northern Illinois Planning Commission, 2001, Proposed Final Report June 2001, 92 p. http://www.nipc.cog.il.us/ commission_approved_draft_6- 18.pdf/).

1999 Illinois Statistical Abstract, 1999: Bureau of Economic and Business Research, College of Commerce and Business Administration, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, table 28-5, p. 720-721.

Stevens, T.H., and E. Kesisoglou, 1984, The effect of price on the demand for water in Massachusetts A case study: Massachusetts Agricultural Experiment Station, College of Food and Natural Resources, Uni- versity of Massachusetts at Amherst, Research Bulletin No. 98/December 1984, 25 p.

Suter, M., R.E. Bergstrom, H.E Smith, G.H. Emrich, W.C. Walton, and T.E. Larson, 1959, Preliminary report on groundwater resources of the Chi- cago region, Illinois: Illinois State Geological Survey, Cooperative Groundwater Report, 89 p.

Turvey, R., 1976, Analyzing the marginal cost of water supply: Land Econom- ics, v. 52, p.158-168.

U.S. Geological Survey, 1985, National Water Summary 1984 Hydrologic events, selected water quality trends, and ground water resources: Reston,

Virginia, U.S. Geological Survey, Water Supply Paper 2275, 467 p.

U.S. Geological Survey, 1995, Esti- mated water withdrawals and use in Illinois, 1988: Urbana, Illinois, U.S. Department of the Interior, Open File Report 95-309.

U.S. Geological Survey, 1996, Esti- mated water withdrawals and use in Illinois, 1990: Urbana, Illinois, U.S. Department of the Interior, Open File Report 95-396.

U.S. Geological Survey, 1999, Estimated water withdrawals and use in Illinois, 1992: Urbana, Illinois, U.S. Depart- ment of the Interior, Open File Reports 95-309, 96-396, and 99-97.

Winstanley, D, and M. Peden, 2000, When a water witch won't work: Illi- nois Issues, November 2000, p. 33-35.

Wong, S.T., 1972, A model on municipal water demand A case study of northeastern Illinois: Land Eco- nomics, v. 48, no. 1, February 1972, p. 34-44.

Recommended Readings

Beecher, J.A., and PC, Mann, 1997, Real water rates: Public Utilities Fortnightly, July 15, 1997, p. 42-46.

Hall, CD., 1996, Economic instruments to mitigate water scarcity Marginal cost rate design and wholesale water markets: Advances in the economics of environmental resources, v. 1: Greenwich, Connecticut and London, JAI Press, p. 3-9.

Hanson, D.A., 1980, Increasing extrac- tion costs and resource prices: Some further results: Bell Journal of Eco- nomics, v. 1 1 , p. 335-34 1 .

Heal, G., 1976, The relationship between price and extraction cost for a resource with a backstop technology: Bell Journal of Economics, v. 7, p. 371-378.

Hotelling, H., 1981, The economics of exhaustible resources: Journal of Political Economy, v. 39, p. 137-175.

Illinois State Water Survey, Water with- drawals in Illinois, 1980, 1982, 1984 and 1986: Champaign, Illinois, Illi- nois State Water Survey in coopera- tion with the U.S. Geological Survey.

Lynne, G.D., 1989, Scarcity rents for water A valuation and pricing model; Comment: Land Economics, v. 65, no. 4, p.420-424.

Moncur, J.E.T., and R.L. Pollock, 1989, Scarcity rents for water A valuation and pricing model: Land Economics, v. 65, no. 4, p. 425-428.

Pindyck, R.S., 1978, The optimum exploration and production of non- renewable resources: Journal of Political Economy, v. 86, p. 841-861.

Zarnikau, J., 1994, Spot market pricing of water resources and efficient means of rationing water during scarcity: Resource and Energy Eco- nomics, v. 16, no. 3, p.189-210.

10

Illinois Minerals I 26

Illinois State Geological Survey

Appendix

Table A1 Counties in 1 1 Illinois regions.

Region

County

Chicago McHenry, Lake, Kane, DuPage, Cook, Kendall, Will, Grundy,

and Kankakee

Rockford Jo Daviess, Stephenson, Winnebago, Boone, Carrol, Ogle,

DeKalb, Lee, and Whiteside

Rock Island Rock Island, Henry, Mercer, Knox, Warren, Henderson,

McDonough, and Hancock

Peoria Bureau, LaSalle, Putnam, Marshall, Stark, Peoria, Tazewell,

Fulton, and Woodford

Champaign Livingston, McLean, Ford, Champaign, and Vermilion

Decatur DeWitt, Piatt, Douglas, Edgar, Coles, Clark, Cumberland,

Shelby, Moultrie, and Macon

Springfield Mason, Logan, Menard, Sangamon, Cass, Morgan, Macoupin,

Montgomery, and Christian

Quincy Adams, Schuyler, Brown, Pike, Scott, Greene, Calhoun,

and Jersey

East St. Louis Madison, Bond, Clinton, Washington, St. Clair, Monroe, and

Randolph

Central Fayette, Effingham, Jasper, Crawford, Marion, Clay, Richland,

Lawrence, Wayne, Edwards, Wabash, and White

Carbondale Jefferson, Hamilton, Perry, Franklin, Jackson, Williamson,

Saline, Gallatin, Union, Johnson, Pope, Hardin, Alexander, Pulaski, and Massac

Table A2 Cost (millions of dollars) of providing water in Chicago, 1987-1997.'

1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997

Source of supply 1.1

Power and pumping 33.7

Purification Total

27.7 62.5

0.1 31.2 25.9 57.2

'Source: Department of Water, City of Chicago.

0.9 35.0 28.8 64.7

0.7 31.3 26.8 58.8

0.6 30.3 30.5 61.4

0.6 31.6 33.0 65.2

0.1 32.7 35.7 68.5

0.4 33.4 43.2 77.0

0.5 38.1 45.6 84.2

0.5 37.8 47.0 85.3

0.2 36.5 48.1 84.8

Table A3 Costs of pumping and supplying water in the Chicago area in 1997.

Source of supply

Power and pumping

Purification

Transmission and distribution

Accounting and collection

Administration and general

Central services and general

fund reimbursement Other expenses Total operating expenses

'Individual rounding causes total not to add up exactly.

Expenditure

Average cost

(million $)

($/1 ,000 gal)

0.20

0.00

36.50

0.09

48.10

0.12

56.10

0.14

10.50

0.03

11.20

0.03

56.80

0.14

2.40

0.01

221.80

0.55'

Illinois State Geological Survey

Illinois Minerals 126 11