Skip to main content

Full text of "Accounting measures of unfunded pension liabilities and bond risk premiums (pension accounting and bond risk premiums)"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


THE  HECKMAN  BINDERY,  INC. 
North  Manchester,  Indiana 


JUST  FONT     SLOT         TITLE 


H  CC  1W 


H  CC  1W 


H  CC  1W 


H  CC  7W 


3R 
aCULTY 
VORKING 
PAPER 

8  1988 

7  NO. 1468-1485 

330 

B385<»,CV"> 
no. 1468-1485 
cop.  2 

<IMPRINT> 
U.  of  ILL. 
LIBRARY 
SANA 


DMF 


BINDING  COPY 


PERIODICAL:    D  CUSTOM         D  STANDARD       □  ECONOMY       □  THESIS 
BOOK      □  CUSTOM 


Di 


Di 


ACCOUNT        LIBRARY     NEW 


RUBOR      TITLE  ID 
SAMPLE 


□ 


NO  VOLS. 
THIS  TITLE 


LEAD  ATTACH. 


ACCOUNT  NAME 

V  OP    ILLINOIS 

ACCOUNT  INTERNAL  I.D. 


FOIL  MATERIAL 

6632      WHI         488 


ISSN. 


BG19124 

I  D.  #2  NOTES 

STX4 

COLLATING 

35 


ADDITIONAL  INSTRUCTIONS 


BINDING  WHEEL 

FREQUENCY 


SYS.  ID. 

1         3 


7  6 


Dept=STX'5       1  Item=  .     !M=[ZY# 
1CR2ST3CR  MARK  BY  #  B4  91] 


SEP  SHEETS      PTS.  BD  PAPER       TAPE  STUBS       CLOTH  EXT 


INSERT  MAT 


PRODUCT  TYPE 


__ 


HBQK. 


1 

/]      FILLER 

GUM  STUB 


SPECIAL  PREP. 


LEAF  ATTACH. 


ACCOUNT  LOT  NO 
ACCOUNT  PIECE  NO 


GROUP  CARD 


vol  mis 


COVER  SIZE 


,/  x 


47 


001247981 


FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  1471 


Accounting  Measures  of  Unfunded  Pension  Liabilities 
and  Bond  Risk  Premiums  (Pension  Accounting  and  Bond 
Risk  Premiums) 


Sara  Ann  Reiter 


SEP  131988 


NOIS 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois.  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  1471 

College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 

University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana- Champaign 

July  1988 


Accounting  Measures  of  Unfunded  Pension  Liabilities 

and  Bond  Risk  Premiums 

(Pension  Accounting  and  Bond  Risk  Premiums) 

Sara  Ann  Reiter,  Assistant  Professor 
Department  of  Accountancy 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/accountingmeasur1471reit 


Accounting  Measures  of  Unfunded  Pension  Liabilities 
And  Bond  Risk  Premiums 
Abstract 


The  research  issue  investigated  in  this  paper  is  whether  accounting 
information  on  unfunded  pension  obligations  is  associated  with  bond  market 
risk  measures.   The  study  provides  further  evidence  linking  pension  numbers 
with  bond  market  risk  measures  and  assesses  the  usefulness  of  SFAS  87  pension 
obligation  measures. 

The  study  uses  a  sample  of  209  electric  utility  new  issues  between  1981 
and  1984.   A  risk  premium  model  is  used  to  test  the  incremental  explanatory 
power  of  net  pension  obligation  measures  for  bond  risk  premiums.   The 
association  of  pension  information  with  bond  risk  premiums  has  not  previously 
been  investigated.   The  study  introduces  bond  risk  premium  methodologies 
commonly  used  in  studying  finance  issues  into  accounting  research. 

The  principal  findings  of  the  study  are  that  net  pension  obligations 
measured  on  a  termination  basis  as  well  as  net  pension  obligation  measures 
which  take  expected  future  benefit  increases  into  account  are  associated  with 
bond  market  risk  measures.   The  conclusion  is  that  SFAS  87  measures  of  net 
pension  obligation  appear  to  be  an  adequate  representation  of  the  market's 
assessment  of  future  cash  flow  obligations  represented  by  defined  benefit 
pension  plans. 

Key  Words:     Risk  premiums,  pensions. 


1.0   INTRODUCTION 

The  research  issue  investigated  in  this  paper  is  whether  accounting 
information  on  unfunded  pension  obligations  is  associated  with  bond  risk 
premiums.   Accounting  disclosures  of  unfunded  pension  obligations  are 
required  to  assist  financial  statement  users  in  assessing  the  risks 
associated  with  future  cash  flows  of  the  firm.   It  is  an  important  empirical 
issue  whether  such  disclosures  are  associated  with  market  risk  measures. 
This  study  provides  further  evidence  linking  pension  numbers  with  bond  market 
risk  measures  and  assesses  the  usefulness  of  SFAS  87  pension  obligation 
measures.   The  study  is  an  extension  of  the  Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  paper 
which  examines  the  associations  of  alternative  measures  of  unfunded  pension 
obligations  with  a  measure  that  best  reflects  the  present  value  of  future 
expected  cash  flows.   Instead  of  determining  associations  with  a  measure  of 
"true"  pension  liability,  this  study  examines  the  association  of  alternative 
net  pension  obligation  measures  with  a  bond  market  risk  measure. 

In  order  to  understand  the  contribution  of  this  study,  it  is  necessary 
to  review  what  is  known  about  the  association  of  pension  measures  with  firm 
risk  and  return.   Table  1  presents  previous  studies  of  the  association  of  net 
pension  liabilities  with  measures  of  firm  risk  and  return.   The  table  is 
organized  by  issue  studied  and  by  pension  benefit  measure  used.   In  all  the 
studies,  it  is  a  maintained  hypothesis  that  true  net  pension  liabilities  are 
associated  with  the  market  value  of  the  firm  or  various  risk  measures.   The 
issue  tested  is  whether  accounting  measures  of  net  pension  liabilities  are 
sufficiently  associated  with  true  pension  liabilities  to  be  associated  with 
market  return  and  risk  measures.   A  number  of  empirical  studies  have  explored 
the  association  of  unfunded  pension  liabilities  with  the  market  price  of  a 


firm's  common  stock.   Several  studies  examine  the  association  of  unfunded 
pension  benefits  with  risk  measures  such  as  common  stock  beta  and  bond 
ratings.   The  general  conclusion  is  that  unfunded  pension  benefits  are 
reflected  in  common  equity  prices  and  risk  measures  such  as  beta  and  bond 
ratings . 

insert  Table  1  here 
This  study  demonstrates  the  association  of  unfunded  pension  obligations 
with  bond  risk  premiums.   Several  of  the  reasons  for  extending  research  to 
risk  premiums  as  the  market  risk  measure  are  that  risk  premiums  represent  a 
bond  market  assessment  of  risk  as  opposed  to  common  stock  prices  or  betas  and 
that  risk  premiums  are  continuous  variables  and  therefore  offer  a  finer 
measurement  of  risk  than  bond  ratings  which  are  categorical  variables.   Bond 
risk  premium  models  have  been  widely  used  in  finance  to  study  a  variety  of 
bond  pricing  issues.   The  sample  consists  of  209  new  issue  electric  utility 
bonds,  debentures  and  long-term  notes  issued  between  1981  and  1984.    New 
issues  are  used  in  order  to  study  risk  premiums  because  thin  bond  market 
trading  and  issue  characteristics  which  change  over  time  make  modeling  of 
risk  premiums  on  outstanding  bonds  quite  difficult.   There  are  three 
advantages  to  the  use  of  utilities.   First,  an  adequate  sample  size  can  be 
attained  since  there  are  many  more  utility  straight  debt  issues  than 
industrial  straight  debt  issues  during  the  early  1980' s.   Second,  since  many 
utilities  routinely  rely  on  the  credit  markets  as  a  source  of  funds,  there  is 
less  likelihood  of  a  self -selection  bias  in  terms  of  the  types  of  firms  which 
come  to  the  credit  markets  during  a  period  of  high  interest  rates.   Finally, 
electric  utilities  represent  a  relatively  homogeneous  operating  risk  group 
and  the  effects  of  debt  equivalent  items,  such  as  unfunded  pension 


obligations,  on  Che  risk  premium  may  be  more  clearly  observed.    Unfunded 
pension  obligations  should  be  associated  with  bond  risk  premiums  since  there 
are  definite  risks  to  bondholders  associated  with  the  future  cash  flow 
commitments  represented  by  unfunded  pension  promises  .  The  study  develops  a 
risk  premium  model  and  investigates  the  association  of  unfunded  pension 
obligations  with  risk  premiums.   Measures  of  pension  obligations  using  SFAS 
87  measurement  principles  are  tested  for  association  with  bond  market  risk 
measures  so  that  the  potential  usefulness  of  SFAS  87  disclosures  is 
evaluated. 

One  contribution  of  the  study  is  that  it  provides  further  evidence 
confirming  the  association  of  accounting  measures  of  net  pension  obligations 
with  market  measures  of  risk  and  return.   Cross -sectional  studies  of  the 
association  between  accounting  disclosures  and  market  risk  and  return 
measures  are  important  in  validating  the  relevance  of  accounting  numbers. 
The  association  of  pension  information  with  bond  risk  premiums  has  not 
previously  been  investigated.   The  second  contribution  is  the  use  of  bond 
market  risk  measures.  This  study  introduces  bond  risk  premium  methodologies 
commonly  used  in  studying  finance  issues  into  accounting  research  and 
provides  some  insights  into  choice  of  appropriate  models  and  solutions  to 
methodological  problems.   The  use  of  a  bond  market  risk  measure  is  an 
important  contribution  of  this  study.   There  is  very  little  empirical 
evidence  on  the  association  of  accounting  numbers  with  bond  market  parameters 
despite  the  importance  of  the  bond  markets  in  new  capital  generation  and  the 
equal  status  of  creditors  with  investors  in  The  Statement  of  Financial 
Accounting  Concepts  No.  1.  "Objectives  of  Financial  Reporting  by  Business 
Enterprises"  (FASB  1978). 


Different  measures  of  pension  benefits  are  explained  in  Section  2. 
Measurement  of  the  pension  variables  is  discussed.   The  research  hypothesis 
is  stated  and  principal  implications  are  introduced.   The  risk  premium  model 
and  the  sample  used  in  the  study  are  described  in  Section  3.   Model 
estimation  and  results  are  presented  in  Section  4.   Several  estimation  issues 
relating  to  model  specification,  collinearity  and  cross-sectional 
correlations  are  evaluated.   Significant  associations  are  found  between  risk 
premiums  and  each  of  the  measures  of  net  pension  obligation.   Conclusions  and 
implications  are  discussed  in  Section  5. 

2.0  PENSION  MEASUREMENT 

2.1  Explanation  of  pension  benefit  measures 

Pension  benefits  are  measured  as  the  present  value  of  future  benefits 
expected  to  be  paid.   The  estimate  of  future  benefits  expected  to  be  paid  can 
reflect  plan  benefit  formulas  applied  to  current  salary  levels  using  service 
accumulated  to  date  or,  at  the  other  extreme,  can  be  based  on  expected  salary 
levels  at  retirement,  expected  future  service  and  expected  plan  amendments. 
Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  and  Schipper  and  Weil  (1982)  conclude  that  a 
measure  based  on  future  salaries  and  expected  future  service  provides  the 
best  information  about  the  future  cash  flow  commitments  of  the  firm.   There 
is  a  basic  trade-off  between  relevance  and  reliability  in  that  using  future 
salary  and  service  estimates  may  decrease  the  reliability  of  pension  benefit 
estimates .  ■* 

The  basic  research  issue  in  the  pension  association  studies  listed  in 
Table  1  is  whether  reported  pension  benefit  measures  are  sufficiently 
relevant  and  reliable  to  be  reflected  in  market  return  and  risk  measures. 
Essentially,  the  issue  tested  is  whether  accounting  measures  of  net  pension 


benefits  are  sufficiently  correlated  with  "true"  net  pension  benefits  to  be 
associated  with  market  risk  and  return  measures.   Pension  benefit  measures 
used  in  the  studies  come  from  pension  disclosures  prepared  under  APB  8,   SEC 
or  SFAS  36  requirements.   The  most  recent  pension  accounting  standard,  SFAS 
87,  becomes  effective  in  1987  for  most  firms  (FASB  1985).   No  studies  to  date 
have  used  SFAS  87  disclosures,  although  Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  test  SFAS 
87  pension  measures  in  a  simulation  setting.   Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  use 
simulation  to  test  directly  which  measure  of  net  pension  liability  is  most 
closely  correlated  with  the  "true"  net  pension  liability.   They  find  that 
although  pension  benefit  measures  based  on  different  assumptions  are  highly 
correlated  with  each  other,  the  correlation  between  net  pension  benefits  is 
much  lower.   They  find  that  net  pension  benefits  measured  as  projected 
benefit  obligations  are  more  highly  correlated  with  "true"  net  pension 
liabilities  than  net  pension  benefits  measured  as  accumulated  benefit 
obligations.   This  finding  is  important  because  the  minimum  net  obligation  to 
be  recognized  on  the  balance  sheet  under  SFAS  87  is  based  on  the  accumulated 
benefit  obligation.   It  may  be,  however,  that  the  accumulated  benefit 
obligation  is  not  the  most  relevant  measure  of  pension  obligation.   This 
study  extends  Selling  and  Stickney  by  testing  the  association  of  various 
pension  benefit  measures  with  a  market  risk  measure  rather  than  a  simulated 
"true"  pension  liability. 

Actual  SFAS  87  pension  benefit  disclosures  cannot  be  used  because  it  is 
necessary  to  use  a  sample  of  new  bond  issues  to  study  risk  premiums.   SFAS  87 
disclosures  have  not  been  available  for  a  sufficient  number  of  years  (firms 
are  not  required  to  adopt  SFAS  87  before  1987  annual  reports)  to  develop  a 
new  issue  sample  using  actual  SFAS  87  numbers.   Approximations  of  SFAS  87 


numbers  are  therefore  calculated  using  conservative  transformation  techniques 
and  the  basic  measurement  principles  underlying  SFAS  87.   In  addition,  an 
estimate  of  economic  pension  liability,  which  takes  additional  expected 
future  cash  flow  commitments  into  account,  is  calculated. 

Two  different  pension  benefit  measures  are  used  in  SFAS  87  -  the 
accumulated  benefit  obligation  and  the  projected  benefit  obligation.   The 
accumulated  benefit  obligation  represents  benefits  earned  to  date  with  no 
future  salary  growth  discounted  at  a  current  annuity  settlement  rate.   In 
other  words,  accumulated  benefit  obligations  represent  termination  benefits. 
The  accumulated  benefit  obligation  forms  the  basis  for  determination  of 
whether  a  minimum  pension  obligation  must  be  recognized  on  the  balance  sheet. 
The  projected  benefit  obligation  takes  future  salary  growth  into  account. 
The  projected  benefit  obligation  is  used  in  the  determination  of  pension 
expense  and  is  presented  in  footnote  disclosures.   The  projected  benefit 
obligation  may  not  fully  reflect  expected  future  cash  flows  since  firms  do 
adjust  benefits  of  retired  workers  and  workers  with  fixed  benefit  formulas 
for  inflation  and  it  can  be  argued  that  pension  benefits  involve  an  implicit 
contract  with  workers  to  make  such  adjustments  in  the  future   (Ippolito  1985, 
1986a, b).   Economic  benefits  represent  pension  benefits  expected  to  be  paid 
rather  than  benefits  contractually  due  to  workers  and  are  therefore  more 
representative  of  expected  future  cash  flows  (Selling  and  Stickney  1986  and 
Schipper  and  Weil  1982) .   An  economic  benefit  measure  is  included  in  the 
study  for  comparison  with  the  projected  benefit  measure  in  order  to  see  if 
the  market  regards  projected  benefits  as  an  adequate  representation  of  future 
cash  flow  commitments. 

insert  Table  2  here 


2.2   Estimation  of  pension  benefit  measures 

The  pension  benefit  measures  used  in  this  study  are  (1)  pension  benefits 
reported  under  SFAS  36,  pension  benefit  measures  reported  under  SFAS  87  -  (2) 
the  accumulated  benefit  obligation  and  (3)  the  projected  benefit  obligation 
and  (4)  economic  pension  benefits  reflecting  the  probable  future  amounts  to 
be  paid  given  implicit  contracts  with  the  workers.   Table  2  presents  a 
comparison  of  pension  benefit  measures  in  terms  of  salary  and  service 
assumptions,  actuarial  methods  and  discount  rates.   The  benefit  measures  are 
calculated  using  the  Bulow  and  Ippolito  transformation  methods  described 
below. 

A  simple  linear  transformation  procedure  is  suggested  by  Bulow  (1979). 
The  underlying  rationale  is  a  comparison  of  pension  benefit  promises  to  a 
consol,  which  is  an  infinite  series  of  future  cash  flows.   The  discount  rate 
for  a  consol  is  one  over  the  interest  rate.   Since  the  duration  of  the 
pension  benefit  stream  is  less  sensitive  to  changes  in  interest  rates  than 
the  duration  of  the  consol,  the  assumption  that  the  change  in  value  of 
pension  benefits  with  regard  to  changes  in  interest  rates  is  proportional  to 
one  over  the  interest  rate  is  a  conservative  assumption  (Bulow,  1979,  p. 49). 
The  Bulow  transformation  is  a  simple  linear  adjustment  with  the  following 
formula: 

bp  -  LR  x  (iR  /  iT) 

where  Lp  -  Transformed  liability 
Lr  -  Reported  liability 
i-p  -  Transformed  interest  rate 
iR  -  Reported  interest  rate 


The  Bulow  transformation  method  is  employed  in  the  pension  studies  which  use 
SFAS  36  footnote  data  (Maher  1987,  Feldstein  and  Morck  1982  and  Landsman  1986 
(uses  a  similar  method)). 

Ippolito  (1986b)  develops  an  approximation  of  the  sensitivity  of  pension 
benefits  to  variation  in  interest  rates  from  empirical  data  using  Department 
of  Labor  reports.   Ippolito  derives  a  model  of  pension  liabilities  and 
estimates  an  equation  using  data  from  over  4,000  plans  in  1978.   The  results 
appear  to  be  quite  reasonable  since  values  for  the  constants  in  his  equation 
conform  to  realistic  assumptions  about  time  to  retirement  and  average 
retirement  period  and  the  sensitivity  of  pension  benefits  to  changes  in 
interest  rates  for  retired  workers  is  not  as  great  as  for  active  workers. 
Ippolito  uses  this  transformation  to  estimate  economic  liabilities  which 
reflect  implicit  promises  to  adjust  future  benefits  for  inflation.   Ippolito 
finds  that  the  estimated  economic  liabilities  conform  with  actual  wage -tenure 
profiles  (Ippolito  1985)  and  with  stock  market  values  (Ippolito  1986a). 
Francis  and  Reiter  (1987)  use  the  Ippolito  adjustment  to  estimate  economic 
pension  benefits.   The  formulas  which  are  used  to  transform  pension  benefits 
are: 

for  active  participants:   Lt/Lr  ~  exp(  -  .077(i-j;  -  iR)) 
for  retired  participants:  Lj/Lr  -  exp(  -  .057(i-j'  -  iR) ) 
The  Ippolito  model  assumes  that  all  plans  have  the  same  average 
retirement  period  for  retired  workers  and  the  same  average  time  to  retirement 
for  active  workers.   If  these  assumptions  have  changed  since  1978,  it  seems 
likely  that  retirement  periods  are  longer  and  that  work  forces  are  younger 
(due  to  the  effects  of  forced  early  retirements  etc.)  so  that  actual 
sensitivities  to  interest  rate  changes  may  be  greater  than  the  model 

8 


indicates.   The  Ippolito  model,  therefore,  represents  a  conservative 
adjustment  process. 

Total  benefits  (vested  plus  nonvested)  are  used  in  the  calculations 
since  accumulated  benefits  approximate  termination  liabilities  and  all 
pension  benefits  are  considered  vested  in  a  voluntary  termination.   Benefit 
measures  which  assume  future  salary  growth  such  as  projected  benefits  and 
economic  benefits  implicitly  assume  that  benefits  will  become  vested.   The 
discount  rates  used  to  determine  the  SFAS  36  disclosures  are  reported  in 
footnote  disclosures  and  the  average  of  the  high  and  low  rates  is  used  when  a 
range  of  rates  is  reported.   The  appropriate  discount  rate  for  SFAS  87 
pension  measures  is  the  annuity  settlement  rate.   The  average  settlement  rate 
published  by  the  Pension  Benefit  Guarantee  Corporation  (PBGC)  is  used  for 
determining  SFAS  87  benefits  and  economic  benefits.   Estimates  of  the 
percentages  of  retired  and  active  workers  (202  and  802  respectively)  are 
determined  using  a  sample  of  utility  pension  plans  from  the  Blue  Book  of 
Pension  Funds. 

The  accumulated  benefit  obligation  is  estimated  by  using  the  Bulow 
method  and  the  PBGC  annuity  settlement  rates  for  each  year.   The  projected 
benefit  obligation  and  the  economic  benefit  obligation  are  estimated  using 
the  Ippolito  method.   The  projected  benefit  obligation  is  basically  the  same 
as  the  accumulated  benefit  obligation  for  benefits  belonging  to  retired 
workers  and  to  workers  whose  benefits  are  not  tied  to  final  pay.   Therefore, 
the  retiree's  benefits  (20Z)  are  adjusted  to  the  PBGC  annuity  rate  and  the 
benefits  of  active  workers  are  adjusted  to  the  average  of  the  spread  between 
the  discount  rate  and  rate  of  salary  growth  and  the  PBGC  rate.   This  assumes 
that  about  50Z  of  the  active  workers  have  benefits  tied  to  final  pay.   In 


order  to  determine  the  appropriate  spread  between  the  discount  rate  and 
assumed  salary  growth  rate,  1986  annual  reports  available  on  NAARS  for  the 
firms  in  the  sample  which  use  SFAS  87  in  1986  (N-20)  are  analyzed.   The 
average  difference  between  the  discount  rate  and  the  compensation  growth  rate 
in  this  sample  is  about  2Z. 

The  accuracy  of  the  transformation  process  for  projected  benefit 
obligations  is  verified  by  comparison  with  the  subsample  of  actual  SFAS  87 
benefit  measures  for  1986.   The  ratio  of  actual  projected  benefits  to 
accumulated  benefits  is  1.35  to  1  while  the  ratio  of  estimated  accumulated 
benefits  to  estimated  projected  benefits  for  the  entire  sample  is  1.48  to  1. 
Since  interest  rate  levels  are  higher  during  1981  through  1983  than  in  1986, 
a  slightly  larger  spread  between  accumulated  benefits  and  projected  benefits 
would  be  expected  for  the  sample  period  so  that  the  transformation  procedure 
is  verified. 

Ippolito  (1986b)  provides  a  conservative  proxy  for  economic  benefits. 
Benefits  for  retired  workers  are  adjusted  to  a  rate  of  1.52  plus  half  of 
inflation  to  reflect  the  experience  of  the  1970 's  when  retired  workers 
received  increases  in  benefits  representing  about  half  of  inflation. 
Benefits  for  active  workers  are  adjusted  to  a  real  rate  of  3Z. 
2.3   Comparisons  of  benefit  measures 

Table  2  presents  descriptive  statistics  for  the  pension  variables  and  a 
correlation  matrix  of  pension  measures.   The  measures  of  estimated  pension 
benefits  from  smallest  to  largest  are  accumulated  benefit  obligations, 
reported  benefits,  projected  benefit  obligations  and  economic  benefit 
obligations.   Accumulated  benefit  obligations  represent  termination  benefits, 
projected  benefit  obligations  take  part  of  expected  future  benefit  increases 

10 


in  account  and  economic  benefit  obligations  reflect  expected  future  benefits 
assuming  that  firms  adjust  benefits  for  inflation.   The  average  funded  status 
of  firms  (pension  assets  divided  by  pension  benefits)  is  1.2  using  reported 
benefits,  1.69  using  accumulated  benefit  obligations,  1.14  using  projected 
benefit  obligations  and  .91  using  economic  benefit  obligations.   The 
correlations  between  the  benefit  measures  are  high  (ie.  .99).  Correlations 
between  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  are  not  as  high.   For  instance,  the 
correlation  between  net  pension  assets  based  on  accumulated  benefit 
obligations  and  net  pension  assets  based  on  economic  benefit  obligations  is 
.62.   These  results  coordinate  with  the  simulation  results  of  Selling  and 
Stickney  (1986)  which  show  a  high  correlation  between  different  pension 
benefit  measures  and  lower  correlations  between  net  pension  assets 
(liabilities).   Since  the  ranking  of  firms  by  net  pension  assets 
(liabilities)  differs  between  measures,  there  is  the  possibility  that  some 
measures  produce  cross -sectional  rankings  which  are  more  highly  correlated 
with  market  risk  measures. 
2.4  Research  Issue 

In  studies  of  the  association  of  unfunded  pension  benefits  with  market 
measures,  the  real  issue  is  whether  accounting  measures  of  pension  obligation 
are  sufficiently  relevant  and  reliable  to  be  reflected.   The  research  issue 
in  this  study  is  whether  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  reported  in  SFAS  36 
footnote  disclosures  and  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  measured  to 
approximate  SFAS  87  pension  measures  and  economic  pension  liabilities  are 
associated  with  bond  risk  premiums.   Theoretically,  Merton  (1974)  has  shown 
that  liabilities  of  the  firm  increase  the  risk  premium  required  on  new  debt 
issues.   Risk  premiums  are  measures  of  the  default  risk  of  firms  issuing 

11 


bonds.   Pension  obligations  represent  liabilities  of  the  sponsoring  firm. 

The  research  issue  is  whether  current  accounting  measurements  of  unfunded 

pension  benefits  are  reflected  in  bond  risk  premiums.   This  is  basically  a 

measurement  issue.   The  research  hypothesis,  stated  in  the  alternate  form, 

is: 

HI:   Unfunded  pension  benefits  information  is  associated  with 
bond  risk  premiums.  Specifically,  the  coefficient  of  net  pension 
assets  (liabilities)  is  inversely  associated  with  risk  premiums. 

The  research  issue  is  tested  by  adding  net  pension  asset  (liability) 
variables  to  a  base  or  control  model  and  testing  for  increases  in  explanatory 
power.    The  sign  and  significance  level  of  the  coefficient  for  the  pension 
variable  is  also  evaluated.   Various  diagnostics  on  the  proper  specification 
of  the  model  and  the  validity  of  the  tests  are  presented  in  Section  4. 

The  second  research  issue,  which  is  addressed  only  in  an  exploratory 
manner,  is  whether  different  measures  of  net  pension  asset  (liability)  have 
different  degrees  of  association  with  bond  risk  premiums.   No  formal  tests  of 
differences  in  association  are  proposed,  however,  informal  comparisons  of  F 
statistics  will  be  made.   Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  find  that  projected  net 
assets  (liabilities)  are  more  highly  correlated  than  accumulated  net  pension 
assets  (liabilities)  with  "true"  net  pension  liabilities.   Furthermore, 
Schipper  and  Weil  (1982),  Selling  and  Stickney  (1986)  and  Ippolito  (1985, 
1986a, b)  claim  that  economic  pension  liabilities  are  more  relevant  than 
termination  measures.   For  these  reasons,  we  would  expect  that  economic  net 
pension  assets  (liabilities)  will  be  most  highly  associated  with  bond  risk 
measures  with  projected  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  next  most  associated 
and  accumulated  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  least  associated. 


12 


The  results  of  the  study  may  have  several  policy  implications.   The 
association  of  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  with  bond  market  risk 
measures  provides  additional  research  evidence  that  the  funded  position  of 
defined  benefit  pension  plans  has  an  impact  on  market  parameters  even  before 
the  SFAS  87  requirement  to  recognize  a  minimum  pension  obligation.   In 
addition,  conclusions  about  the  usefulness  of  various  SFAS  87  requirements 
may  be  possible.   Evidence  from  this  study  can  help  evaluate  the  usefulness 
of  SFAS  87  requirements  that  (1)  pension  asset  and  liability  amounts  are 
separately  disclosed,  (2)  a  termination  liability  measure  is  used  in 
determining  the  minimum  pension  liability  to  be  recognized  and  (3) 
realization  of  probable  future  benefit  increases  is  limited  to  future  salary 
growth  assumptions  and  excludes  probable  other  future  benefit  increases. 

3.0  RISK  PREMIUM  MODEL  AND  SAMPLE 

3.1  Risk  Premium  Model  Development 

The  risk  premium  on  corporate  bonds  can  be  defined  as  the  difference 
between  the  yield  on  a  risky  security  and  that  on  a  security  that  is 
risk- free  but  identical  in  all  other  respects.   The  classic  study  on  the 
determinants  of  bond  yields  is  Fisher  (1959)  which  hypothesizes  that  bond 
risk  premiums  are  a  function  of  the  default  risk  of  the  firm  and  of  the 
marketability  of  the  bond  issue.   Appendix  A  summarizes  a  number  of  models 
used  in  various  studies  to  explain  bond  yields  or  risk  premiums.   Factors 
found  important  by  researchers  include  indenture  provisions  (such  as  term  to 
maturity,  sinking  funds  and  secured  status) ,  call  risk,  macroeconomic  factors 
(such  as  business  cycle  effects)  and  marketability. 

The  dependent  variable  (DYIELD)  is  formed  by  subtracting  the  yield  to 
maturity  of  a  U.S.  Treasury  issue  from  the  offering  yield  (OFYLD)  of  a  new 

13 


utility  issue.   Fung  and  Rudd  (1986)  indicate  that  it  is  important  to  use  the 
previous  day's  treasury  issue  closing  yield  to  match  with  the  offering  yield 
on  new  securities.   The  independent  variables  are  chosen  to  proxy  for 
maturity  and  indenture  characteristics,  call  risk,  macroeconomic  factors  and 
default  risk. ' 

Term  to  maturity  is  expected  to  be  directly  related  to  risk  premiums  due 
to  the  increased  exposure  to  interest  rate  risk  with  increased  time  to 
maturity.   A  variable  for  the  presence  of  a  sinking  fund  is  added  to  the 
model  since  the  necessity  of  entering  into  complex  sinking  fund  agreements 
for  the  enhanced  security  of  the  borrower  is  related  to  the  perceived  quality 
of  the  issuer. 

The  period  of  the  study,  from  1981  through  1984,  is  a  period  of  high 
market  interest  rates  so  that  call  risk  is  an  important  factor  in  pricing  the 
bonds  sold.   Future  refinancing  at  lower  interest  rates  seems  probable  for 
many  of  these  issues  and  investors  are  willing  to  pay  extra  for  call 
protection  to  lock  in  the  high  yields.   Degree  of  call  protection  is  proxied 
by  the  difference  between  the  yield  to  first  call  or  refunding  and  the 
offering  yield.   Effects  from  both  the  length  of  the  deferment  period  and  the 
amount  of  the  call  premium  are  taken  into  account  by  this  measure. 

It  is  necessary  to  control  for  macroeconomic  factors  since  the  sample 
period  spans  three  years.   Previous  studies  (Jaffee  1975  and  Cook  and 
Hendershott  1978)  find  evidence  that  risk  premiums  vary  with  the  business 
cycle.   A  number  of  economic  indicators  are  used  in  these  studies  and  the 
variable  with  the  most  consistent  significant  explanatory  power  is  the  index 
of  consumer  sentiment.   The  index  of  consumer  sentiment,   which  is  based  on 
data  collected  by  the  University  of  Michigan  and  is  described  in  detail  by 

14 


Fair  (1971),  is  used  in  this  model  to  control  for  macroeconomic  effects. 
Since  the  risk  premium  rises  as  overall  interest  rates  rise  (Cook  and 
Hendershott  1978),  the  level  of  interest  rates  is  also  included  as  an 
independent  variable. 

Financial  ratios  are  used  to  proxy  for  default  risk.  Evidence  of  the 
connection  between  various  financial  ratios  and  default  risk  of  utilities  is 
gathered  from  Standard  &  Poor's  Rating  Guide  (1979),  Melicher's  (1974)  factor 
analysis  of  utility  ratios  and  Altman  and  Katz ' s  (1976)  bond  rating 
prediction  study.  The  following  categories  of  factors  are  found  to  be 
important:   cash  flow  adequacy,  asset  protection,  capitalization  and  earning 
stability.   Variables  representing  cash  flow  adequacy,  capitalization  and 
earnings  protection  are  cash  flow  to  construction  expenditures,  the 
debt- equity  ratio  and  the  property  funding  ration  (long  term  debt  to 
property,  plant  and  equipment).   The  coefficient  of  variation  of  return  on 
equity  for  five  years  represents  earning  stability.   Pretax  interest  coverage 
is  one  of  the  most  important  financial  ratios  used  by  bond  raters  (Standard  & 
Poor's  1979).   One  potential  drawback  in  using  a  utility  sample  is  that 
during  the  1980' s,  factors  which  are  not  reflected  in  the  financial  ratios  of 
utilities,  such  as  potential  problems  with  bringing  new  plants  on-line,  begin 
to  significantly  and  rapidly  alter  the  risk  of  several  utilities.   A  dummy 
variable  NUKE  is  included  for  utilities  which  are  experiencing  problems 
connected  with  their  nuclear  generating  facilities  at  the  time  of  the  bond 

o 

issue . ° 

Table  3  summarizes  the  risk  premium  model  variables  and  expected  signs. 
Sample  descriptive  statistics  are  presented  in  Table  4. 

insert  Tables  3  and  4  here 

15 


3.2   Sample 

The  sample  consists  of  new  issues  of  public  utility  bonds  between 
February  23,  1981  and  February  29,  1984.   The  starting  date  of  the  study 
coordinates  with  the  earliest  availability  of  pension  footnote  disclosures 
mandated  by  SFAS  No.  36.  Issues  between  February  23,  1981  and  February  29, 
1984  are  included  in  the  sample  if  the  issuers  are  considered  to  be  electric 
utilities  by  Moody's  Public  Utility  Manual  and  a  full  set  of  pension  and 
financial  information  is  available.  Lack  of  publicly  available  pension 
footnote  information  causes  22  observations  to  be  dropped.   Because  it  is  not 
comparable  with  other  bond  issues,  one  deep  discount  issue  is  not  included  in 
the  sample.   The  final  sample  consists  of  209  issues. 

The  offering  date,  offering  yield  and  other  terms  of  each  issue, 
including  indenture  terms,  are  gathered  from  Moody's  Bond  Survey.  The 
Investment  Dealer's  Digest,  and  Moody's  Public  Utility  Manual.  Descriptive 
information  necessary  to  code  the  NUKE  variable  comes  from  Standard  &  Poor's 
CreditWeek  analysis  of  new  issues.   Treasury  yields  are  from  the  Wall  Street 
Journal. 

The  primary  source  for  financial  variables  is  Standard  &  Poor's 
CreditWeek  and  secondary  sources  are  annual  reports  and  Moody's  Public 
Utility  Manual.  One  advantage  of  using  CreditWeek  data  is  timeliness.   In 
many  cases  the  financial  data  is  reported  up  to  the  nearest  quarter  to  the 
issue  date  and  capitalization  data  are  pro  forma.   The  information  used  to 
form  the  pension  variables  is  collected  from  the  FASB  36  pension  data  bank 
(Version2,  Columbia  University)  and  from  annual  reports. 


16 


4.   ESTIMATION  AND  RESULTS 
4.1   Estimation  Issues 

insert  Table  5  here 

The  risk  premium  model  is  estimated  using  Ordinary  Least  Squares 
regression.   Results  are  reported  in  Table  5.   The  increase  in  explanatory 
power  for  the  addition  of  pension  variables  is  evaluated  using  the  general 
linear  test.   The  formula  is: 

F*  -  SSE  (R)  -  SSE  (?)         /  SSE  (F) 

d.f.R  -  d.f.F  d.f.F 

Where  SSE  (R)  and  SSE  (F)  and  d.f.R  and  d.f.F  are  the  sum  of  squared  errors 
and  degrees  of  freedom  for  the  reduced  and  full  models  respectively.   F*  is 
distributed  by  the  F  distribution  with  ((d.f.F  -  d.f.R),  d.f.F)  degrees  of 
freedom  (Neter  and  Wasserman  1974) . 

There  are  three  potential  problems  which  are  important  in  evaluating 
results.   First,  spurious  results  could  arise  if  the  model  is  not  specified 
properly.   Second,  results  could  be  influenced  by  severe  collinearity . 
Finally,  cross-sectional  correlations  could  affect  the  statistical 
significance  of  the  results.   These  three  potential  problems  are  evaluated 
and  I  find  that  the  model  appears  to  be  well-specified,  that  collinearity 
between  pension  and  other  variables  is  not  a  problem  and  that  the 
significance  of  the  results  is  not  generated  by  cross-sectional  correlations. 
4.1.1  Model  Specification 

One  facet  of  model  fit  is  explanatory  power.   The  control  model,  without 
the  net  pension  asset  (liability),  has  an  adjusted  R-squared  of  60. 5X  which 
is  typical  for  a  risk  premium  model.   All  variables  have  the  expected  signs 
except  for  the  debt-to-equity  ratio  and  all  coefficients  except  for 

17 


coefficient  of  variation  of  return  on  equity  are  significantly  different  from 
zero  at  a  10X  significance  level.   The  unexpected  sign  of  debt-to-equity 
appears  to  be  due  to  a  collinearity  problem  between  debt-to-equity  and  the 
property  funding  ratio  which  is  discussed  further  in  Section  4.1.2. 

Since  the  sample  period  spans  three  years,  I  test  to  see  if  different 
values  of  the  financial  ratios  and  pension  variables  would  be  expected  in 
different  years.   The  financial  ratios  and  pension  variables  are  calculated 
at  December  31,  1980,  1981  and  1982  for  the  22  electrical  utilities  in  the 
Standard  &  Poor's  40  utilities  index.   T- tests  are  performed  to  see  if  the 
levels  of  the  financial  ratios  and  pension  variables  are  different  for  this 
group  of  firms  between  the  three  years.   No  significant  differences  in 
financial  ratios  or  pension  variables  is  found.   Therefore,  no  bias  is 
introduced  by  including  financial  ratios  and  pension  variables  of  issues 
spanning  this  three  year  period  in  the  same  model. 

Ordinary  least  squares  assumptions  of  normality  of  the  dependent 
variable  and  residuals  are  met.   Tests  for  normality  (Stevens  1974)  are 
performed  for  the  dependent  variable  and  residuals.   The  null  hypothesis  of 
normality  cannot  be  rejected  in  either  case.   A  Goldfeld-Quandt  test 
(Goldfeld  and  Quandt  1965)  is  performed  to  test  for  heteroscedasticity .   The 
resulting  F  statistic  is  not  significant  (1.25  for  degrees  of  freedom  71, 
71).   The  conclusion  is  that  the  model  appears  to  be  well-specified  and  that 
results  are,  therefore,  not  caused  by  the  pension  variables  proxying  for  the 
effects  of  incorrect  model  specification. 
4.1.2   Collinearity  Problems 

Another  concern  when  evaluating  results  is  that  severe  collinear 
problems  may  affect  the  results.   Collinearity  diagnostics  (Belsley,  Kuh  and 

18 


Welsch  1981)  indicate  that  there  are  strong  collinear  associations  in  the 
sample  between  three  groups  of  variables:   the  intercept,  the  index  of 
consumer  sentiment,  the  level  of  interest  rates  and  interest  coverage;  the 
debt- to -equity  ratio  and  the  property  funding  ratio;  and  the  level  of 
interest  rates,  the  property  funding  ratio  and  interest  coverage.   No  strong 
collinear  associations  involve  the  pension  variables,  however.   Another 
diagnostic  for  collinear  problems,  the  adjusted  R-square  of  a  regression  of 
the  pension  variable  on  the  other  independent  variables,  is  reported  in  Table 
6.   The  pension  variables  are  not  highly  associated  with  the  other 
independent  variables.   The  simple  correlations  between  pension  variables  and 
the  other  independent  variables  are  presented  in  Table  6.   The  highest  simple 
correlation  is  the  .29  correlation  between  the  debt-to-equity  ratio  and  the 
reported  net  pension  asset  (liability).   This  level  of  correlation  is  well 
below  the  threshold  level  needed  to  cause  collinearity  problems  (Belsley,  Kuh 
and  Welsch  1981) .   Collinearity  between  the  pension  variables  and  the  other 
independent  variables  is  not,  therefore,  biasing  the  results. 

insert  Table  6  here 
4.1.3  Cross -sectional  Correlations 

Finally,  it  is  possible  that  cross-sectional  correlations  within  the 
sample  lead  to  an  overstatement  of  statistical  significance  of  the 
coefficients.   The  sample  observations  span  the  time  period  between  February 
24,  1981  and  February  22,  1984  so  that  there  is  no  concentration  in  calendar 
time.   Another  problem  may  arise  due  to  multiple  issues  by  the  same  firm. 
The  209  issues  included  in  the  sample  represent  72  separate  issuers.   This  is 
because  many  utilities  routinely  come  to  the  bond  market  on  a  yearly  basis. 
If  the  model  is  not  well-specified,  individual  issuer  financial  condition  may 

19 


not  be  well  controlled  for  and  correlations  between  the  residuals  of  issues 
by  the  same  firm  could  result  in  overstatement  of  the  statistical 
significance  of  the  results.   In  order  to  see  is  this  is  an  important  factor, 
the  model  is  run  on  a  subsample  consisting  of  only  one  issue  per  issuer. 
Significance  levels  are  similar  for  the  subsample  and  the  full  sample.   This 
indicates  that  multiple  issues  do  not  lead  to  overstatement  of  significance 
levels.   F  statistics  for  the  increase  in  explanatory  power  in  the  single 
issue  sample  are  reported  in  Table  6. 
4.2   Results 

The  results  of  the  risk  premium  model  tests  are  presented  in  Table  5. 
When  the  reported  net  pension  asset  (liability)  is  added  to  the  control 
model,  there  is  a  significant  increase  in  explanatory  power  (F-10.25).   In 
addition,  the  coefficient  is  negative  and  significant  as  expected.   Similar 
results  are  obtained  when  the  accumulated  net  pension  asset  (liability) 
(F-6.89),  projected  net  pension  asset  (liability)  (F-7.75)  and  economic  net 
pension  asset  (liability)  (F-4.17)  variables  are  added  to  the  control  model. 
In  conclusion,  all  the  pension  measures  are  significantly  associated  with 
risk  premiums. 

Counter  to  expectations,  economic  and  projected  net  assets  (liabilities) 
are  not  more  highly  associated  with  risk  premiums  than  accumulated  net  assets 
(liabilities).  In  fact,  it  seems  that  economic  net  assets  (liabilities)  are 
the  least  closely  associated.  This  result  is  not  consistent  with  Selling  and 
Stickney  (1986),  which  finds  that  projected  net  assets  (liabilities)  are  more 
highly  correlated  with  "true"  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  than 
accumulated  net  pension  assets  (liabilities).  Since  the  economic  net  asset 
(liability)  measure  takes  more  expected  future  cash  flows  into  account,  it 

20 


was  expected  to  be  more  closely  related  to  a  market  risk  measure  than 
accumulated  or  projected  benefit  obligations. 
5.0   CONCLUSIONS 

The  principal  finding  of  this  study  is  that  accounting  measures  of  net 
pension  asset  (liabilities)  (or  simple  transformations  of  accounting 
measures)  are  associated  with  bond  market  risk  measures.   This  indicates  that 
market  risk  and  return  measures  reflect  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  even 
before  balance  sheet  recognition  is  required.   The  different  pension  benefit 
measures,  accumulated,  projected  and  economic  benefits,  are  highly  correlated 
but  net  pension  assets  (liabilities)  formed  with  the  different  measures  are 
less  highly  correlated.   Therefore,  the  SFAS  87  requirements  for  separate 
disclosure  of  pension  assets  and  liabilities  appear  to  be  justified.   The  use 
of  accumulated  net  assets  (liabilities)  as  the  basis  for  liability 
recognition  appears  to  be  justified  also,  since  accumulated  net  assets 
(liabilities)  are  as  closely  associated  with  bond  risk  premiums  as  net  asset 
measures  which  take  future  benefit  increases  into  account.   Since  economic 
net  assets  (liabilities)  are  less  closely  associated  with  risk  premiums  than 
projected  net  assets  (liabilities),  it  appears  that  SFAS  87  pension  measures 
are  an  adequate  representation  of  the  market's  assessment  of  future  cash  flow 
obligations  despite  the  fact  that  the  projected  benefits  measure  only  takes  a 
portion  of  expected  future  benefit  increases  into  account.   Therefore,  SFAS 
87  disclosures  appear  to  provide  optimal  information  to  users  while  taking  a 
conservative  position  on  premature  realization  of  obligations. 

One  limitation  of  the  study  is  the  use  of  estimated  SFAS  87  pension 
measures.   Results  should,  therefore,  be  considered  preliminary  in  nature. 
The  principal  qualification  of  the  research  methodology  is  that  specification 

21 


of  an  appropriate  model  is  extremely  important  in  achieving  internal 
validity.   Although  the  risk  premium  modeling  approach  used  is  not  common  in 
accounting  research,  it  is  a  widely  used  methodology  in  finance  studies. 
Furthermore,  diagnostics  of  model  fit  do  not  indicate  any  problems  with 
misspecif ication.   Finally,  results  using  a  utility  sample  may  not  be  fully 
generalizable  to  industrial  firms.   Creditors  may  view  pension  obligations  of 
utilities  in  a  different  manner  and  may  not  be  as  interested  in  evaluating 
long-term  cash  flow  commitments  as  when  examining  non- regulated  firms.   It  is 
possible,  therefore,  that  creditors  might  evaluate  termination  benefits, 
projected  benefits  and  economic  benefits  differently  for  regulated  and 
industrial  firms. 


The  author  gratefully  acV^oviodees  the  support  of  the  Peat  Marwick  Research 
Fellowship  program.  :es  to  thank  members  of  her  dissertation 

committee,  particularly  Jert  Francis  and  Doug  Emery,  and  participants  of  the 
workshop  at  the  University  of  Illinois  for  their  helpful  comments  on  earlier 
drafts  of  this  paper. 


22 


1.  Lys  (1984)  finds  that  the  debt-equity  ratio  has  little  power  to  explain 
debt  default  risk  unless  variables  to  control  for  total  firm  risk  are 
included  in  the  model.  In  addition,  capital  structure  research  indicates  that 
there  are  different  typical  debt  levels  for  firms  across  industry  groups 
(DeAngelo  and  Masulis  1980  and  Bowen,  Daley  and  Huber  1982). 

2.  The  fact  that  utilities  are  regulated  industries  does  not  invalidate 
their  use  in  this  study.   Public  utility  regulation  does  not  guarantee 
returns  to  bondholders  or  payment  of  employee  pensions.   Rate-making  is  often 
not  particularly  timely,  a  phenomena  known  as  regulatory  lag.   In  times  of 
inflation  and  rising  fuel  prices,  utilities  suffer  from  problems  of  attrition 
(replacement  costs  of  plant  and  equipment  exceed  historical  costs)  and 
erosion  (actual  operating  expenses  exceed  those  embedded  in  the  rates) .   In 
many  ways,  utilities  face  an  environment  not  very  different  from  that  of 
competitive  firms  (Howe  and  Rasmussen  1982) . 

3.  In  addition,  accountants  may  be  constrained  by  the  concept  of 
realization  from  using  future  service  estimates  in  determining  the  present 
value  of  benefits  to  be  paid  in  the  future. 

4.  Economic  benefits  differ  from  the  "true"  pension  liability  in  Selling 
and  Stickney  (1986)  in  that  the  present  value  of  future  expected  service  is 
not  incorporated.   The  economic  benefit  measure  simply  reflects  expectations 
that  benefits  will  be  adjusted  for  expected  future  inflation. 

5.  Statistically  significant  increases  in  explanatory  power  do  not  imply 
that  there  is  a  large  economic  benefit  to  be  earned  by  considering  the 
additional  factor.   It  is  basically  interesting  to  know  that  accounting 
numbers  which  are  designed  to  be  helpful  in  assessing  risk  are  associated 
with  market  measures  of  risk  and  return.   The  bulk  of  what  we  know  about 

23 


accounting  numbers  is  based  on  association  tests.   It  is  not  reasonable  to 
expect  that  addition  of  an  incremental  piece  of  accounting  information  to  any 
but  an  extremely  misspecified  model  would  result  in  a  dramatically  large 
increase  in  explanatory  power. 

6.  Gonedes  and  Dopuch  (1974)  assert  that  associations  of  alternative 
accounting  disclosures  with  market  measures  cannot  determine  which  disclosure 
is  "best"  because  of  market  imperfections.  As  Lev  and  Ohlson  (1982)  point 
out,  however,  there  is  an  intrinsic  value  in  knowing  that  accounting  measures 
which  are  designed  to  be  helpful  is  assessing  risk  are  correlated  with  market 
risk  and  return  measures.  Therefore,  it  is  of  interest  to  note  which  measure 
of  pension  benefits  is  most  closely  associated  with  bond  risk  measures. 

7.  Two  factors  often  mentioned  in  other  studies  are  not  controlled  for 
explicitly  in  this  model:   coupon  tax  effects  and  marketability.   When  bonds 
are  purchased  at  a  substantial  discount,  a  portion  of  the  expected  return  is 
the  capital  gain  on  the  difference  between  maturity  value  and  purchase  price 
and  this  capital  gain  advantage  is  priced  by  the  market.   In  a  study  using 
new  issues,  coupon  tax  effects  are  not  important,  however.   Although 
marketability  does  play  a  role  in  bond  pricing,  there  has  been  little  support 
for  the  marketability  proxies  used  in  previous  studies. 

8.  An  association  between  regulatory  climate  and  bond  ratings  has  been 
demonstrated  (Pinches,  Singleton  and  Jahankhani  1978).  Various  agencies,  for 
example  Value  Line,  provide  ratings  of  regulatory  climate  by  state.  Use  of 
these  rankings  would  provide  a  more  objective  measure  of  regulatory  climate 
but  because  of  the  speed  with  which  circumstances  surrounding  the 
construction  of  nuclear  facilities  change  within  the  time  period  of  this 
study,  the  more  timely  CreditWeek  information  is  used. 

24 


REFERENCES 


Abdel-khalik,  A.  R. ,  Thompson,  R.  B.  and  Chen,  R.  D.  1981.  Effects  on  bond 
pricing  and  on  bond  rating.  In  The  Economic  Effects  on  Leases  of  FASB  No. 
13.  Accounting  for  Leases  (Abdel-khalik,  A.R. ,  principal  researcher) 
Stamford,  Connecticut:  Financial  Accounting  Standards  Board,  pp.  163-191. 

Altman,  E.  I.  and  Katz  ,  S.  1976.  Statistical  bond  rating  classification  using 
financial  and  accounting  data.  In  Proceedings  of  the  Conference  on  Topical 
Research  in  Accounting  (Schiff,  M.  and  G.  Sorter,  eds . )  New  York:  New  York 
University,  pp.  205-239. 

Barrett,  W.  B.,  Heuson,  A.  J.  and  Kolb,  R.  W.  March  1986a.  The  effect  of 
Three  Mile  Island  on  utility  bond  risk  premia:   A  note.  The  Journal  of 
Finance  41(1):  255-261. 

.  Winter  1986b.  The  differential  effects  of  sinking  funds  on  bond 


risk  premia.  The  Journal  of  Financial  Research  9(4):  303-312. 

Belsley,  D.  A.,  Kuh,  E.  and  Welsch,  R.  E.  1980.  Regression  Diagnostics 
New  York:   John  Wiley  &  Sons. 

Berndt,  E.  R. ,  Sharp,  K.  C.  and  Watkins ,  G.  C.  December  1979.  Utility  bond 
rates  and  tax  normalization.  Journal  of  Finance  34(5):  1211-1220. 

Bowen,  R.  M. ,  Daley,  L.  H.  and  Huber,  C.  C,  Jr.  Winter  1982.  Evidence  on 
the  existence  and  determinants  of  inter- industry  differences  in  leverage. 
Financial  Management  11(4):  10-20. 

Bulow,  J.  I.  1979.  Analysis  of  pension  funding  under  ERISA.  National  Bureau 
of  Economic  Research  Working  Paper  No.  402. 

Cook,  T.  Q.  and  Hendershott,  P.  H.  September  1978.  The  impact  of  taxes,  risk 
and  relative  security  supplies  on  interest  rate  differentials.  The  Journal 
of  Finance  33(4):  1173-1186. 

Daley,  L.  A.  April  1984.  The  valuation  of  reported  pension  measures  for 
firms  sponsoring  defined  benefit  plans.  The  Accounting  Review  59(2): 
77-198. 

DeAngelo,  H.  and  Masulis,  R.  W.  March  1980.  Optimal  capital  structure  under 
corporate  and  personal  taxation.  Journal  of  Financial  Economics  8(1): 
3-29. 

Dhaliwal,  D.  S.  October  1986.  Measurement  of  financial  leverage  in  the 
presence  of  unfunded  pension  obligations.  The  Accounting  Review  61(4): 
651-661. 

Ederington,  L. ,  Yawitz,  J.  B.  and  Roberts,  B.  H.  Fall  1987.  The 

informational  content  of  bond  ratings.  The  Journal  of  Financial  Research 
10(3):  211-226. 

25 


Fair,  R.  C.  1971.  A  Short-run  Forecasting  Model  of  the  United  States  Economy 
Lexington,  Massachusetts:  Heath. 

Feldstein,  M.  and  Morck,  R.  1982.  Pension  funding  decisions,  interest  rate 
assumptions  and  share  prices.  National  Bureau  of  Economic  Research 
Working  Paper  No.  938. 

Feldstein,  M.  and  Seligman,  S.  September  1981.  Pension  funding,  share 
prices,  and  national  savings.  The  Journal  of  Finance  36(4):  801-824. 

Financial  Accounting  Standards  Board.  1978.  Statement  of  Financial  Accounting 
Concepts  No.  1:  Objectives  of  Financial  Reporting  by  Business 
Enterprises .  Stamford,  Connecticut:  Financial  Accounting  Standards  Board. 

.  1985.  Statement  of  Financial  Accounting  Standards  No.  87: 


Employers'  Accounting  for  Pensions.  Stamford,  Connecticut:  Financial 
Accounting  Standards  Board. 

Fisher  L.  June  1959.  Determinants  of  risk  premiums  on  corporate  bonds. 
The  Journal  of  Political  Economy  67(3):  217-237. 

Francis,  J.  R.  and  Reiter,  S.  A.  April  1987.  Determinants  of  corporate 
pension  funding  strategy.  Journal  of  Accounting  and  Economics  9(1): 
35-59. 

Fung,  W.  K.  H.  and  Rudd,  A.  July  1986.  Pricing  new  corporate  bond  issues: 
An  analysis  of  issue  cost  and  seasoning  effects.   The  Journal  of 
Finance  41(3):  633-643. 

Goldfeld,  S.  and  Quandt,  R.  June  1965.  Some  tests  for  homoskedasticity . 
Journal  of  the  American  Statistical  Association  60(310):  539-547. 

Gonedes,  N.  J.  and  Dopuch,  N.  1974.  Capital  market  equilibrium,  information 
predictions,  and  selecting  accounting  techniques:    Theoretical 
framework  and  review  of  empirical  work.  Studies  On  Financial  Accounting 
Objectives:  1974  Supplement  to  Journal  of  Accounting  Research  12:  48-129. 

Howe,  K.  M.  and  Rasmussen,  E.  F.  1982.  Public  Utility  Economics  and  Finance. 
Englewood  Cliffs,  New  Jersey:  Prentice-Hall,  Inc. 

Ippolito,  R.  A.  December  1985.  The  labor  contract  and  true  economic  pension 
liabilities.  American  Economic  Review  75(5):  1031-1043. 

.  January- February  1986a.  The  economic  burden  of  corporate  pension 


liabilities.  Financial  Analysts  Journal  42(1):  22-34. 

,  1986b.  Pensions.  Economics  and  Public  Policy.  Homewood,  Illinois: 

Dow- Jones  -  Irwin. 

Jaffee,  D.  M.  July  1975.  Cyclical  variations  in  the  risk  structure  of 
interest  rates.  Journal  of  Monetary  Economics  1(3):  309-325. 

26 


Kidwell,  D.  S.,  Marr ,  M.  W.  and  Thompson,  G.  R.  April  1987.  Shelf 

registration:  Competition  and  market  flexibility.  Journal  of  Law  and 
Economics  30(1):  181-206. 

Landsman,  W.  October  1986.  An  empirical  investigation  of  pension  and 
property  rights.  The  Accounting  Review  61(4):  662-691. 

Lev,  B.  and  Ohlson,  J. A.  1982.  Market-based  empirical  research  in 

accounting:   A  review,  interpretation,  and  extension.  Studies  on  Current 
Research  Methodologies  in  Accounting:  A  Critical  Evaluation  Supplement  to 
Journal  of  Accounting  Research  20:  249-322. 

Lys ,  T.  April  1984.  Mandated  accounting  changes  and  debt  covenants.  Journal 
of  Accounting  and  Economics  6(1):  39-65. 

Maher,  J.  J.  October  1987.  Pension  obligations  and  the  bond  credit  market: 
An  empirical  study.  The  Accounting  Review  62(4):  785-798. 

Martin,  L.  J.  and  Henderson,  G.  V.,  Jr.  December  1983.  On  bond  ratings  and 
pension  obligations,  A  note.  Journal  of  Financial  and  Quantitative 
Analysis  18(4):  463-470. 

Melicher,  R.  W.  March  1974.  Financial  factors  which  influence  beta 
variations  within  an  homogeneous  industry  environment.  Journal  of 
Financial  and  Quantitative  Analysis  9(1):  231-242. 

Merton,  R.  C.  May  1974.  On  the  pricing  of  corporate  debt:   The  risk 
structure  of  interest  rates.  The  Journal  of  Finance  29(2):  449-470. 

Neter,  J.  and  Wasserman,  W.  1974.   Applied  Linear  Statistical  Models 
Homewood,  Illinois:  Richard  D.  Irwin,  Inc. 

Oldfield,  G.  S.  February  1977.  Financial  aspects  of  the  private  pension 
system.  Journal  of  Money.  Credit,  and  Banking  9(1):  48-54. 

Pinches,  G.  E. ,  Singleton,  J.  C.  and  Jahankhani,  A.  Summer  1978.  Fixed 
coverage  as  a  determinant  of  electric  utility  bond  ratings.  Financial 
Management  7(2):  45-55. 

Rogowski,  R.  J.  and  Sorensen,  E.  H.  Spring  1985.  Deregulation  in  investment 
banking:   Shelf  registrations,  structure,  and  performance.   Financial 
Management  14(1):  5-15. 

Schipper,  K.  and  Weil,  R.  L.  October  1982.  Alternative  accounting 
treatments  for  pensions.  The  Accounting  Review  57(4):  806-824. 

Selling,  T.  I.  and  Stickney,  C.  P.  Winter  1986.  Accounting  measures  of 
unfunded  pension  liabilities  and  the  expected  present  value  of  future 
pension  cash  flows.  Journal  of  Accounting  and  Public  Policy  5(4): 
267-285. 


27 


Smith,  R.  L.  July  1987.  The  choice  of  issuance  procedure  and  the  cost  of 

competitive  and  negotiated  underwriting:   An  examination  of  the  impact  of 
Rule  50.  The  Journal  of  Finance  42(3):  703-720. 

Standard  &  Poor's  Rating  Guide.  1979.  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  Inc. 

Stevens,  M.  A.  September  1974.  EDF  statistics  for  goodness  of  fit  and  some 
comparisons.  Journal  of  the  American  Statistical  Association   69(347): 
730-737. 


28 


Appendix  A 


Yield  Studies 


Author (s) 

Saiple 

and  data 

Abdel- 

1975-79 

khalik, 

178  bonds 

Thompson 

i  Chen 

[1981] 

Barrett, 

1977-B2 

Meuson, 

Public 

Kolb 

Utilities 

[1986a] 

76  bonds 

Issue  investigated 


Association  of  risk 
prenuis  with 
capitalized  lease 
obligations 

Effect  of  Three  Nile 
Island  on  utility 
bond  risk  premiums 


Dependent  Factors  represented  by  independent  variables 
variable 

Risk     Log  of  coefficient  of  variation  in  earnings(t), 
preiiui   Log  of  larket  value  of  equity  to  book  value  of 
(log)    debt  it),  Log  of  market  value  of  all  traded 
debt (I) 


R 
square 

.48  - 

.90 


Risk     Ten  to  maturity!!),  First  Mortgage!!),  Sinking  .63 
premiui   fund  it),  Log  of  issue  size,  Bond  rating 
duMies(t),  Discount  factor (t),  Level  of 
interest  rates(t),  Change  in  industrial 
production (1),  Change  in  lonetary  policy (t), 
Shape  of  yield  curved),  Three  Nile  Island 
vanables(t) 


Barrett, 

1977-83 

Effect  of  sinking 

Risk 

Heuson  i 

76  public 

funds  on  bond 

preiiui 

Kolb 

utility 

yields 

[1986b] 

issues 

Berndt, 

1962-76 

Effect  of  rate 

Tax 

Sharp, 

Electric 

normalization  for 

Adjusted 

Hatkins 

Utilities 

deferred  taxes 

Yields 

[1979] 

90-93 

Cook  i 

1961-73 

Deteriinants  of  the 

Risk 

Hendershott  Yield  series   risk  preiiui 

preiiui 

[1978] 

Utility  Aa 

Ederington, 

2728/79  t 

Deter ii runts  of  bond 

Yield  to 

Yawitz  fc 

2/27/81 

yields 

■aturity 

Roberts    176  and 
[1987]     180  bonds 


Ten  to  taturity(t),  First  aortgage(t),  Log  of  .63 
issue  size,  Bond  rating  dunies(t),  Discount 
factor (t),  Call  preiiui(t),  Level  of  interest 
rates(t),  Shape  of  yield  curved),  Change 
in  industrial  production (t),  Change  in  monetary 
policy (t) ,  Sinking  fund  variables(t) 

Debt  to  equity(t),  Current  assets,  Coupon  (t),  .48-. 85 
Exchange  listing,  Rate  normalization  (!) , Change 
in  loney  supply,  Change  in  6NP  growth (!), 
Market  power,  Location 

Index  of  consumer  sentiment (t),  Employment 
index,  Call(t),  Level  of  interest  rates(t), 
Relative  supply 

Financial  ratios!!),  Bond  ratings(t),        .80-. 87 
Subordinate  status! t),  Call  and  capital 
gain(t),  Period  of  call  protection 


Fisher 

1927,1932, 

Deteriinants  of  the 

Risk 

[19591 

1937,1949 

risk  preiiui 

preiiui 

1933 

(log) 

45-88  firms 

Fung  fc 

1983-83 

Effects  of  shtlf 

Risk 

Rudd 

123  -em 

registration 

premium 

[1986] 

issues 

Jaffee 

1954-69 

Cyclical  variations 

Risk 

[1975] 

Quarterly 

in  the  risk  structure 

1  spreads 
between 
ratings 

Log  of  earnings  variability!!),  Log  of  period   .73- 
of  solvency (t),  Log  of  equity  to  debt  ratio(t), 
Log  of  market  value  of  bonds  outstanding!!) 


.81 


Level  of  interest  rates!!),  Log  of  ten  to     .79 
maturity!!),  Log  of  years  to  first  call,  Log 
of  issue  size,  Quality!!),  Industrial  sector!!), 
Financial  sector,  Shelf  registration 

Index  of  consumer  sentiment!!),  Unemployment   .65-. 75 
rate,  Growth  rate  of  retained  earnings!!), 
6rowth  of  capital  investment (I),  6rowth 
of  output.  Baa  interest  level!!),  Term 
to  laturity(l),  Total  float,  Coupon!!) 


Appendix  A 


Yield  Studies 


KidMell , 

1982-83 

Effects  of  shelf 

Harr  & 

111  new 

registration 

Thoapson 

issues 

(1987] 

Rogoaski  & 

1981-83 

Effect  of  shelf 

Sorensen 

307  new 

registration 

C1985] 

issues 

Risk    Rating  duaaies(t),  Level  of  rates(t),  Interest  .78 
prenui   volatility (t) ,  Sinking  fund ( t) ,  Call  feature, 
Log  of  issue  size(t),  Nuaber  of  bids(t), 

Sale  iet hod 


Offering 
yields 


Saith 

1977-85 

Choice  of  under- 

Yield to 

[1987] 

380  new 

issues 

utilities 

writing  aethods 

issuer 

Level  of  interest  rates(t),  Trend  of  rates,    .88 
Supply  of  new  issues! I),  Log  of  issue  size, 
Bond  rating  duaaies(t),  Average  aaturity(t), 
Call  protection  aeasure,  Interaction  of  call 
and  aaturity,  Shelf  registration!!) 

Rating  duaaies(t),  Log  of  issue  size,  Log  of 
nuaber  of  issues  by  fira(t),  Call  protection, 
First  call  preaiua,  Years  to  first  call, 
Characteristics  of  investaent  banker,  Variance 
in  interest  rate  level,  Level  of  interest  rates(t) 


Table  1 

PENSION  STUDIES 


Association  of  unfunded 
pension  obligations  with: 

Theoretical  Pension  Liability 
Measures 

Selling  and  Stickney  (1986) 

Market  Value  of  Equity  and/or 
Stockholders'  Equity 

Landsman  (1986) 

Daley  (1984) 

Feldstein  and  Morck  (1982) 
Feldstein  and  Seligman  (1981) 

Oldfield  (1977) 

Systematic  Risk  -  Common  Stock  Beta 
Dhaliwal  (1986) 

Bond  Ratings 

Maher  (1987) 

Martin  and  Henderson  (1983) 


Pension  Measures  Used 


SFAS  87  -  Simulated  Benefits 


SFAS  36  disclosures:   Total  and 

Standardized 

APB  8  disclosures  -  Unfunded  Vested 

Benefits  and  Pension  Expense  and  SEC 

disclosures  -  Unfunded  Past  Service  Cost 

SFAS  36  disclosures  -  Vested  and 

Standardized 

APB  8  disclosures  -  Unfunded  Vested 

Benefits  and  SEC  disclosures  -  Unfunded 

Past  Service  Cost 

APB  8  disclosures  -  Unfunded  Vested 

Benefits 


APB  8  disclosures  -  Unfunded  Vested 
Benefits 


SFAS  36  disclosures  -  Vested,  Total  and 

Standardized 

SEC  disclosures  -  Unfunded  Past  Service 

Cost 


31 


Table  2 
COMPARISON  OF  PENSION  BENEFIT  MEASURES 


Benefit  measures: 


Reported  under  SFAS  36 


Assumptions : 
Salary 


Current 
salaries 


Service 


Accumulated 
to  date 


Actuarial 
method 

Unit  credit 


Discount 
rate 

Various 


Accumulated  benefits 
SFAS  87 


Current 
salaries 


Accumulated 
to  date 


Unit  credit 


Annuity 

settlement 

rates 


Projected  benefits 
SFAS  87 


Expected 

future 

salaries 


Accumulated 
to  date 


Unit  credit 


Annuity 

settlement 

rates 


Economic  benefits 


Expected 
future 
salaries 
and  benefit 
increases 


Accumulated 
to  date 


"True"  pension  benefits 


Expected 
future 
salaries 
and  benefit 
increases 


Expected 


DEFINITION  OF  PENSION  VARIABLES 


Reported  net  asset  (liability) 


(Fair  market  value  of  plan  assets  - 
Reported  pension  benefits)  /  Permanent 
capitalization 


Accumulated  net  asset  (liability)   (Fair  market  value  of  plan  assets 

Accumulated  benefit  obligation)  / 


Projected  net  asset  (liability) 


Economic  net  asset  (liability) 


Permanent  capitalization 

(Fair  market  value  of  plan  assets  - 
Projected  benefit  obligation)  / 
Permanent  capitalization 

(Fair  market  value  of  plan  assets  - 
Economic  benefit  obligation)  /  Permanent 
capitalization 


32 


Table  2  -  continued 
DESCRIPTIVE  STATISTICS 


Reported  pension  benefits 
Accumulated  benefit  obligation 
Projected  benefit  obligation 
Economic  benefit  obligation 

Reported  funding  ratio 
Accumulated  funding  ratio 
Projected  funding  ratio 
Economic  funding  ratio 

Reported  net  asset  (liability) 
Accumulated  net  asset  (liability) 
Projected  net  asset  (liability) 
Economic  net  asset  (liability) 


Mean   Standard 

Minimum 

Maximum 

Deviation 

173.828 

197 

.783 

5.620 

1 

,103.000 

122.412 

140 

.705 

4.738 

779.899 

180.263 

205 

.192 

6.539 

1 

,143.695 

226.622 

259 

.362 

7.926 

1 

,438.250 

1.193 

.364 

.602 

2.645 

1.698 

.677 

.722 

5.103 

1.139 

.375 

.580 

2.769 

.908 

.298 

.461 

2.146 

.006 

.014 

-.031 

.053 

.020 

.015 

-.020 

.062 

.004 

.014 

-.039 

.049 

-.009 

.017 

-.069 

.041 

PEARSON  CORRECTION  COEFFICIENTS 


Reported  benefits 
Accumulated  benefits 
Projected  benefits 
Economic  benefits 


Reported  net  asset 

(liability) 
Accumulated  net  asset 

(liability) 
Projected  net  asset 

(liability) 
Economic  net  asset 

(liability) 


Reported 

Accumulated 

Projected 

Economic 

benefits 

benefits 

benefits 

benefits 

1.000 

.987 

.996 

.997 

1.000 

.997 

.995 

1.000 

.999 
1.000 

Reported 

Accumulated 

Projected 

Economic 

net  asset 

net  asset 

net  asset 

net  asset 

(liability) 

(liability) 

(liability) 

(liability) 

1.000 

.783 

.947 

.859 

1.000 

.849 

.617 

1.000 

.933 
1.000 

33 


Table  3 

Risk  Premium  Model 

Variable   Expected  Description 
Sign 

Dependent  Variable 
DYIELD         Risk  premium 

Maturity  and  Issue  Characteristics 

MATYR     +    Years  to  maturity 
SF        +    Sinking  fund 

Political  and  Regulatory  Risk 
NUKE      +    Trouble  with  nuclear  plant 

Call  Risk 
DFYLD     -    Offering  yield  -  Yield  to  first  call 

Macroeconomic  Factors 

MOOD      -     Index  of  consumer  sentiment 
TYIELD    +    Level  of  Treasury  yields 

Financial  Variables 

CONST  -  Cash  flow  to  construction  expenditure 

DE  +  Debt- to -equity  ratio 

PROP  +  Property  funding  ratio 

ROE  +  Coefficient  of  variation  of  return  on  equity 

COV  -  Pretax  interest  coverage 

Pension  Variables 

SUNB      -     (Pension  plan  assets  -  reported  benefits) 

to  permanent  capitalization 
TUNB      -     (Pension  plan  assets  -  accumulated  benefits) 

to  permanent  capitalization 
PUNB  (Pension  plan  assets  -  projected  benefits) 

to  permanent  capitalization 
EUNB     -     (Pension  plan  assets  -  economic  benefits) 

to  permanent  capitalization 


34 


Variable 


Table  4 

DESCRIPTIVE  STATISTICS 

Sample  Descriptives   N-209 

Mean  Standard  Minimum  Maximum 
deviation 


DATE 

2/ 

'25/* 

51 

2/2? 

>/84 

ISSUE  SIZE 

84 

.4928 

43 

.1312 

10 

250 

(Million  $) 

COUPON  RATE 

14. 

,7992 

1, 

.9368 

10. 

875 

18. 

75 

% 

OFFERING  YIELD 

14, 

,8779 

1. 

,9467 

10. 

95 

18. 

75 

X 

TREASURY  YIELD 

12. 

5356 

1. 

,5238 

9. 

45 

15. 

78 

X 

YEARS  TO  MATURITY 

20, 

,7034 

10, 

,2304 

5 

33 

Years 

PERIOD  OF  CALL 

OR 

REFUNDING  PROTECTION 

5. 

2895 

2, 

0331 

0 

30 

Years 

NO  CALL  OR  REFUND  PROTECTION 
CALL  PROTECTION 
REFUNDING  PROTECTION 
FIRST  MORTGAGE 


Number 

Percent 

Coded  1 

in  Sample 

2 

1.1% 

21 

10.0% 

186 

88.  9X 

201 

96.  IX 

Model  Descriptives 


Variable  Mean 


Standard  Minimum  Maximum  Number   Percent 
Deviation  Coded  1  in  Sample 


Dependent  Variable 
DYIELD    2.3422    .8879 


.43 


4.82 


Independent  Variables 

MATYR 

20.7034 

10.2304 

5 

33 

SF 

87 

41.63 

NUKE 

61 

29.19 

DFYLD 

-1.1539 

.6116 

-3.57 

0 

MOOD 

74.8584 

10.3838 

62 

100.1 

TYIELD 

12.5356 

1.5238 

9.45 

15.78 

CONST 

29.2928 

28.3328 

-96 

132 

DE 

50.1239 

5.3128 

31.80 

67 

PROP 

45.1029 

5.7715 

30.09 

72.1 

ROE 

.1274 

.0716 

.01 

.46 

COV 

2.6281 

.6269 

1.63 

4.77 

Distribution  of  Sample  Issues  by  Year 


Year 

Number 

Percent 

1981 

69 

33. 0Z 

1982 

78 

37.3% 

1983 

57 

27.  3X 

1984 

5 

2.4X 

35 


Table  5 

REGRESSION  RESULTS 
N-209,  Dependent  variable  -  DYIELD 


Reduce 

d  Model 

Full  Model 

Full  Model 

Contrc 

1  Model 

Add  Reported 

Add  Ac 

cumulated 

net  pension 

net  pension 

asset 

(liability) 

asset 

(liability) 

Variable 

Pre- 

Coeffi 

T   Prob. 

Coeffi 

T   Prob. 

Coeffi 

T   Prob 

dicted 

cient 

Stat. 

cient 

Stat. 

cient 

Stat. 

sign 

Intercept 

3.285 

3.394  <.001 

3.213 

3.396  <.001 

3.579 

3.727  <.001 

MATYR 

+ 

.039 

5.937  <.001 

.039 

6.129  <.001 

.039 

6.146  <.001 

SF 

+ 

.188 

2.309   .011 

.173 

2.162   .016 

.177 

2.191   .015 

NUKE 

+ 

.218 

2.294   .011 

.189 

2.024   .022 

.217 

2.312   .011 

DFYLD 

- 

-.241 

-2.455   .008 

-.232 

-2.422   .008 

-.236 

-2.438   .008 

MOOD 

- 

-.035 

-7.779  <.001 

-.035 

-7.901  <.001 

-.036 

-8.069  <.001 

TYIELD 

+ 

.176 

4.999  <.001 

.175 

5.097  <.001 

.173 

4.981  <.001 

CONST 

- 

-.009 

-4.875  <.001 

-.008 

-4.689  <.001 

-.008 

-4.331  <.001 

DE 

+ 

-.019 

-2.231   .013 

-.012 

-1.406   .081 

-.016 

-1.827   .035 

PROP 

+ 

.013 

1.567   .059 

.010 

1.214   .113 

.010 

1.211   .114 

ROE 

+ 

.712 

1.213   .113 

.619 

1.079   .141 

.544 

.935   .176 

COV 

- 

-.463 

-5.108  <.001 

-.494 

-5.540  <.001 

-.500 

-5.530  <.001 

REPORTED  NET 

PENSION  ASSET 

(LIABILITY) 

- 

-9.293 

-3.201  <.001. 

ACCUMULATED  NET 

PENSION  ASSET 

(LIABILITY) 

- 

-7.206 

-2.626  .009 

Adjusted  R- Square 


60.50 


62.27 


61.65 


F  Statistic   * 


10.248 


6.894 


*  The  F  statistics  are  from  general  linear  tests  of  differential  explanatory 
power  of  the  full  models  over  the  reduced  model  (without  pension  variables).   F* 
at  a  significance  level  of  .10  Is  approximately  2.75  for  degrees  of  freedom  (1, 
196). 


36 


Table  5  -  continued 


Full  Model 

Full  Model 

Add  Pr 

ojected 

Add  Ec 

onomic 

net  pension 

net  pension 

asset 

(liability) 

asset 

(liability) 

Variable 

Pre- 

Coeffi 

T   Prob . 

Coeffi 

T   Prob 

dicted 

cient 

Stat. 

cient 

Stat. 

sign 

Intercept 

3.297 

3.464  <.001 

3.141 

3.263  <.001 

MATYR 

+ 

.040 

6.181  <.001 

.040 

6.103  <.001 

SF 

+ 

.169 

2.101   .018 

.171 

2.106   .018 

NUKE 

+ 

.188 

1.991   .024 

.180 

1.876   .031 

DFYLD 

- 

-.236 

-2.448   .008 

-.240 

-2.468   .007 

MOOD 

- 

-.036 

-8.044  <.001 

-.035 

-7.900  <.001 

TYIELD 

+ 

.175 

5.047  <.001 

.178 

5.101  <.001 

CONST 

- 

-.008 

-4.858  <.001 

-.009 

-5.089  <.001 

DE 

+ 

-.014 

-1.572   .059 

-.015 

-1.712   .044 

PROP 

+ 

.011 

1.255   .106 

.012 

1.371   .086 

ROE 

+ 

.657 

1.138   .128 

.744 

1.278   .101 

COV 

- 

-.489 

-5.462  <.001 

-.476 

-5.279  <.001 

PROJECTED  NET 

PENSION  ASSET 

(LIABILITY) 

- 

-7.794 

-2.784   .003 

ECONOMIC  NET 

PENSION  ASSET 

(LIABILITY) 

- 

-4.866 

-2.049  .021 

Adjusted  R- Square 

61.81 

61.13 

F  Statistic  * 

7.752 

4.169 

*  The  F  statistics  are  from  general  linear  tests  of  differential  explanatory 
power  of  the  full  models  over  the  reduced  model  (without  pension  variables).   F* 
at  a  significance  level  of  .10  is  approximately  2.75  for  degrees  of  freedom  (1, 
196). 


37 


Table  6 

REGRESSION  DIAGNOSTICS 

CORRELATION  BETWEEN  PENSION  VARIABLES  AND  OTHER  INDEPENDENT  VARIABLES 

Pearson  correlation  coefficients  - 
*   significant  at  .05  level 

Reported    Accumulated  Projected  Economic 
net  asset   net  asset    net  asset   net  asset 
(liability)  (liability)  (liability)  (liability) 


MAT 

-.022 

.042 

.024 

.014 

SF 

-.062 

-.072 

-.072 

-.064 

NUKE 

-.119 

-.043 

-.132 

-.195* 

DFYLD 

.032 

-.026 

-.014 

-.021 

MOOD 

.029 

-.015 

-.035 

-.063 

TYIELD 

.027 

-.020 

.032 

.093 

CONST 

.107 

.162* 

.058 

-.034 

DE 

.296* 

.189* 

.259* 

.250* 

PROP 

.064 

.008 

.044 

.048 

ROE 

.022 

-.042 

.022 

.060 

COV 

-.117 

-.064 

-.109 

-.125 

MULTIPLE  R2** 

.073 

.050 

.057 

.083 

**  Coefficient  of  determination  between  each  pension  variable  and  all  other 
independent  variables. 

F  STATISTICS  -  SINGLE  ISSUE  MODEL 

Reported    Accumulated  Projected   Economic 
net  asset   net  asset    net  asset   net  asset 
(liability)  (liability)  (liability)  (liability) 


One  observation  per 
issuer  N-71 


10.438 


4.938 


8.944 


6.389 


*  The  F  statistics  are  from  general  linear  tests  of  differential  explanatory 
power  of  the  full  models  over  the  reduced  model  (without  pension 
variables).   F*  at  a  significance  level  of  .10  is  approximately  2.79  for 
(1,59). 


38 


HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC. 

JUN95 

Bod  •Ta-PW'  N.  MANCHESTER. 
INDIANA  46963