Skip to main content

Full text of "Capital : a critical analysis of capitalist production"

See other formats


^^'';  H>„ 


rvf:'' 


V  ' 


■fu 


University  of  California  •  Berkeley 

From  the  Bequest 

of 

Dorothy  K.  Thomas 


c^^ 


CAPITAL 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2007  with  funding  from 

IVIicrosoft  Corporation 


http://www.archive.org/details/capitalcriticalaOOmarxrich 


0^ctJj<2c(i    V  6^-ijin  0 


CAPITAL: 

A  CRITICAL  ANALYSIS  OF  CAPITALIST 
PRODUCTION 

By  KARL  MAEX 


TRANSLATED  FROM  THE  THIRD  GERMAN  EDITION,  BY 
SAMUEL  MOORE  AND  EDWARD  AVELING 


AND   EDITED   BY 


FREDERICK    ENGELS 


VOL.  I. 


LONDON: 

SWAN    SONNENSCHEIN,    LOWEEY,    &    CO., 

PATERNOSTER    SQUARE. 

1887. 


8.  Cowan  <fc  Co.,  Strathmore  Printing  Works,  Perth. 


CONTENTS. 


Editor's  Preface, 
Author's  Prefaces- 


-I.  To  the  First  Edition, 
II.  To  the  Second  Edition, 


PAGE 

ix 

XV 

xxi 


PART  I. 

commodities  and  MONET. 

Chapter  I.— Commodities,    .               .               .               .               .  .1 

Section  1. — The  two  Factors  of  a  Commodity  :   Use  Value  and  Value  (the 

Substance  of  Value  and  the  Magnitude  of  Value),    .                .  .1 

Section  2. — The  Twofold  Character  of  the  Labour  embodied  in  Commodities,  8 

Section  3. — The  Form  of  Value,  or  Exchange  Value,          .                .  .14 

A.  Elementary  or  Accidental  Form  of  Value,               .                .  .16 

1.  The  two  Poles  of  the  Expression  of  Value :    Relative  Form  and 

Equivalent  Form,               .                .                .                .  .16 

2.  The  Relative  Form  of  Value,               .                .                .  .17 

[a. )  The  Nature  and  Import  of  this  Form,      .                .  .17 

(6. )  Quantitative  Determination  of  Relative  Value,      .  .          21 

3.  The  Equivalent  Form  of  Value,          .                .                .  .24 

4.  The  Elementary  Form  of  Value  considered  as  a  Whole,  .          29 

B.  Total  or  Expanded  Form  of  Value,           .                 .                .  .32 

1.  The  Expanded  Relative  Form  of  Value,             .                .  .32 

2.  The  Particular  Equivalent  Form,        .                .                .  .           33 

3.  Defects  of  the  Total  or  Expanded  Form  of  Value,           .  .           34 
a  The  General  Form  of  Value,      .                .                .                ,  .35 

1.  The  altered  Character  of  the  Form  of  Value,    .                .  .35 

2.  The  interdependent  Development  of  the  Relative  Form  of  Value, 

and  of  the  Equivalent  Form,             .                .                .  .38 

3.  Transition  from  the  General  Form  to  the  Money  Form,  .          39 
D.  The  Money  Form,       ......  40 

Section  4. — The  Fetishism  of  Commodities  and  the  Secret  thereof,  .  ,          41 

Chapter  II. — Exchange,        .               .               .               .               .  .56 

Chapter  III, — Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,              ,  .          66 

Section  1.  — The  Measure  of  Value,        .                .               .                .  .66 

Section  2. — The  Medium  of  Circulation,               .                .                .  .          76 

a.  The  Metamorphosis  of  Commodities,          .               .  .76 

6.  The  Currency  of  Money,               .                .                .  .          88 

c.  Coin,  and  symbols  of  Value,        .               ,               .  .        100 

Section  3. — Money,                  .               .               .               ,               .  .        105 

a.  Hoarding,       .                .               .               ,               .  .        106 

6.  Means  of  Payment,       .....        Ill 

c.  Universal  Money,           .               .               .                ,  .        ]  19 

PART  II. 

THE  transformation  OF  MONEY  INTO  CAPITAL. 

Chapter  IV.— The  General  Formula  for  Capital,              .  123 

Chapter  V. — Contradictions  in  the  General  Formula  of  Capital,    .  .        133 

Chapter  VI.  -The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power,                .  .        145 


VI 


Contents. 


PART  III. 


THE  PRODUCTION    OP  ABSOLUTE  SURPLUS-VALUE. 

PAOB 

Chapter  VII. — The  Labour  Process  and  the  Process  of  producing  Surplus- 
Value,  .......        156 

Section  1. — The  Labour  Process  or  the  Production  of  Us3-Value,      .  .        156 

Section  2. — The  Production  of  Surplus- Value,      ....        166 

Chapter  VIIL— Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital,  .  .        180 

Chapter  IX.— The  Eate  of  Surplus-Value,         .  .  .  .194 

Section  1. — The  Degree  of  Exploitation  of  Labour-Power,  .  .         194 

Section  2. — The  Representation  of  the  Components  of  the  Value  of  the  Pro- 
duct by  corresponding  proportional  Parts  of  the  Product  itself,  .        203 
Sections.— Senior's  "Last  Hour,"        .               .               .               .               .207 

Section  4. — Surplus-Produce,  .....        213 

Chapter  X.— The  Working-Day,  .  .  .  .  .214 

Section  1. — The  Limits  of  the  Working-Day,        ....         214 

Section  2. — The  Greed  for  Surplus-Labour.     Manufacturer  and  Boyard,         .         218 
Section  3. — Branches  of  English  Industry  without  Legal  Limits  to  Exploita- 
tion, .  .  .  .  .  .  .227 

Section  4.— Day  and  Night  Work.    The  Relay  System,     .  .  .241 

Section  5. — The  Struggle  for  a  Normal  Working-Day.     Compulsory  Laws  for 
the  Extension  of  the  Working-Day  from  the  Middle  of  the  14th  to  the 
End  of  the  17th  Century,  .  .  .  .  .249 

Section  6. — The  Struggle  for  a  Normal  Working-Day.     Compulsory  Limita- 
tion by  Law  of  the  Working-Time.     The  English  Factory  Acts,  1833  to 
1864,  .  .  .  .  .  .  .263 

Section  7. — The   Struggle  for  a  Normal  Working-Day.     Re-action  of  the 

English  Factory  Acts  on  Other  Countries,  .  .  .        284 

Chapter  XL— Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus-Value,  .  .  .289 


PART  IV. 

PRODUCTION  OF  RELATIVE  SURPLUS -VALUE. 

Chapter  XII.— The  Concept  of  Relative  Surplus- Value,  .  .  .300 

Chapter  XIII.— Co-Opera tion,  .  .  .  .  .311 

Chapter  XIV. — Division  of  Labour  and  ^Manufacture,      .  .  .        327 

Section  l.*=-Twofold  Origin  of  Manufacture,  ....  327 
Section  2.— The  Detail  Labourer  and  his  Implements,        .  .  .        330 

Sections. — The  two  Fundamental  Forms  of  Manufacture:    Heterogeneous 

Manufacture,  Serial  Manufacture,  ....        333 

Section  4.— Division  of  Labour  in  Manufacture,  and  Division  of  Labour  in 

Society,  .  .  .  .  .  .  .343 

Section  5.— The  Capitalistic  Character  of  Manufacture,     .  .  353 


VOL.  II. 


Chapter  XV.— Machinery  and  Modern  Industry, 

Section  1.— The  Development  of  Machinery, 

Section  2.— The  Value  transferred  by  Machinery  to  the  Product, 


365 
365 
382 


Contents.  vli 


Section  3.— The  Proximate  Effects  of  Machinery  on  the  Workman,  .        391 

a.  Appropriation  of  Supplementary  Labour-Power  by  Capital. 

The  Employment  of  Women  and  Children.  ,  .        391 

6.  Prolongation  of  the  Working-Day,  .  .  .        400 

c.  Intensification  of  Labour,  ....        407 

Section  4.— The  Factory,         .  .  .  .  .  .418 

Section  5. — The  Strife  between  Workman  and  Machinery,  .  .        427 

Section  6. — ^The  Theory  of  Compensation  as  regards  the  Workpeople   dis- 
placed by  Machinery,    ......        438 

Section  7. — Repulsion  and  Attraction  of  Workpeople  by  the  Factory  System. 

Crises  of  the  Cotton  Trade,  .  .  .  .  .449 

Section  8. — Revolution  effected  in  Manufacture,  Handicrafts,  and  Domestic 

Industry  by  Modern  Industry,     .....         462 

a.  Overthrow  of  Co-Operation  based  on  Handicraft  aud  on  Divi- 
sion of  Labour,  .  .  .  .  .         462 

6.  Re-action  of  the  Factory  System  on  Manufacture  and  Domes- 
tic Industries,  .....        464 

c.  Modern  Manufacture,   .....        466 

d.  Modern  Domestic  Industry,         ....        469 
€.  Passage  of  Modern  Manufacture  and  Domestic  Industry  into 

Modern  Mechanical  Industry.  The  Hastening  of  this  Re- 
volution by  the  Application  of  the  Factory  Acts  to  those  In- 
dustries,      ......        474 

Section  9. — The  Factory  Acts.    Sanitary  and  Eductional  Clauses  of  the  same. 

Their  general  Extension  in  England,  .  .  .        485 

Section  10. — Modern  Industry  and  Agriculture,  .  ,  .        512 

PART.  V. 

THE  PRODUCTION  OF  ABSOLUTE  AND  OF   RELATIVE  SURPLUS  VALUE. 
OhapterXVI.— Absolute  and  Relative  Surplus- Value,     .  .  .         516 

Chapter  XVII. — Changes  of  Magnitude  in  the  Price  of  Labour-Power  and  in 

Surplus-Value,   .  .  .  .  .  .527 

I.  Length  of  the  Working  Day  and  Intensity  of  Labour  constant.     Pro- 

ductiveness of  Labour  variable,        ....         528 

II.  Working  Day   constant.      Productiveness  of  Labour   constant.     In- 

tensity of  Labour  variable,  ....         533 

III. — Productiveness  and  Intensity  of  Labour  constant.     Length  of  the 

Working  Day  variable,      .....         535 
IV.  Simultaneous  Variations  in  the  Duration,  Productiveness,  and  In- 
tensity of  Labour,  .....         537 
(1.)  Diminishing    Productiveness  of  Labour   with  a    simultaneous 

Lengthening  of  the  Working  Day,  .  .  .         537 

(2.)  Increasing  Intensity  and  Productiveness  of  Labour  with  simul- 
taneous Shortening  of  the  Working  Day,  .  .        539 
Chapter  XVIII. — Various  Formulae  for  the  Rate  of  Surplus -Value,               .        541 

PART  VI. 

wages. 
Chapter  XEX. — ^The  Transformation  of  the  Value  (and  respectively  the  Price) 

of  Labour- Power  into  Wages,  .  .  .  .        545 

Chapter  XX.— Time-Wages,  .....        553 

Chapter  XXI.— Piece-Wages,  .....        561 

Chapter  XXII.— National  Differences  of  Wages,  .  .  .570 


VIU 


Contents 


PART  VII. 

THE  ACCUMULATION  OP  CAPITAL. 

Chapter  XXIII.— Simple  Reproduction,  .  .  .  . 

Chapter  XXIV. — Conversion  of  Surplus-Value  into  Capital, 

Section  1. — Capitalist  Production  on  a  progressively  increasing  Scale.  Transi- 
tion of  the  Laws  of  Property  that  characterise  Production  of  Com- 
modities into  Laws  of  Capitalist  Appropriation, 

Section  2. — Erroneous  Conception,  by  Political  Economy,  of  Reproduction 
on  a  progressively  increasing  Scale, 

Section  3. — Separation  of  Surplus-Value  into  Capital  and  Revenue.  The 
Abstinence  Theory,  ..... 

Section  4. — Circumstances  that,  independently  of  the  proportional  Division 
of  Surplus-Value  into  Capital  and  Revenue,  determine  the 
Amount  of  Accumulation.  Degree  of  Exploitation  of  Labour- 
Power.  Prodiictivity  of  Labour.  Growing  Difference  in  Amount 
between  Capital  employed  and  Capital  consumed.  Magnitude 
of  Capital  advanced,  ..... 

Section  5. — The  so-called  Labour  Fund,  .  .  .  . 

Chapter  XXV. — The  General  Law  of  Capitalist  Accumulation, 

Section  1.  -  The  increased  Demand  for  Labour-Power  that  accompanies 
Accumulation,  the  Composition  of  Capital  remaining  the  same, 

Section  2. — Relative  Diminution  of  the  Variable  Part  of  Capital  simul 
taneously  with  the  Progress  of  Accumulation  and  of  the  Concen 
tration  that  accompanies  it,  . 

Section  3. — Progressive  Production  of  a  Relative  Surplus-Population,  oi 
Industrial  Reserve  Army,  .... 

Section  4. — Different  Forms  of  the  Relative  Surplus-Population.  The  General 
Law  of  Capitalistic  Accumulation,  . 

Section  5. — Illustrations  of  the  General  Law  of  Capitalist  Accumulation, 
a.  England  from  1846  to  1866, 
6.  The  badly  paid  Strata  of  the  British  Industrial  Class 

c.  The  Nomad  Population, 

d.  Effect  of  Crises  on  the  best  paid  Part  of  the  "Working  Class, 

e.  The  British  Agricultural  Proletariat, 

/.  Ireland,  ..... 


PAQB 

577 
592 


592 
598 


610 
621 
625 

625 


635 

642 

655 
664 
664 
670 
681 
685 
691 
719 


PART  VIIL 

THE  SO-CALLED  PRIMITIVE  ACCUMULATION. 

Chapter  XXVL— The  Secret  of  Primitive  Accumulation,                .               .  736 
Chapter  XXVII. — Expropriation  of  the  Agricultural  Population  from  the 

Land,                   ......  740 

Chapter  XXVIII.  Bloody  Legislation  against  the  Expropriated  from  the 
End  of  the  15th  Century.     Forcing  down  of  "Wages  by  Acts  of 

Parliament,         ......  758 

Chapter  XXIX.— Genesis  of  the  Capitalist  Farmer,  .  .  .766 
Chapter  XXX. — Reaction  of  the  Agricultural  Revolution  on  Industry.  Crea- 
tion of  the  Home  Market  for  Industrial  Capital,  .  .  769 
Chapter  XXXL— Genesis  of  the  Industrial  Capitalist,  .  .  .  774 
Chapter  XXXII. — Historical  Tendency  of  Capitalistic  Accumulation,  .  786 
Chapter  XXXIIL— The  Modern  Theory  of  Colonization,  .  .  790 
"Worksand  Authors  quoted  in  "Capital."      .               .               ,  801 


EDITOR'S  PREFACE. 


THE  publication  of  an  English  version  of  *'Das 
Kapital  "  needs  no  apology.  On  the  contrary,  an 
explanation  might  be  expected  why  this  English  version 
has  been  delayed  until  now,  seeing  that  for  some  years  past 
the  theories  advocated  in  this  book  have  been  constantly 
referred  to,  attacked  and  defended,  interpreted  and  mis- 
interpreted, in  the  periodical  press  and  the  current 
literature  of  both  England  and  America. 

When,  soon  after  the  author's  death  in  1883,  it  be- 
came evident  that  an  English  edition  of  the  work  was 
really  required,  Mr.  Samuel  Moore,  for  many  years  a 
friend  of  Marx  and  of  the  present  writer,  and  than 
whom,  perhaps,  no  one  is  more  conversant  with  the 
book  itself,  consented  to  undertake  the  translation  which 
the  literary  executors  of  Marx  were  anxious  to  lay  be- 
fore the  public.  It  was  understood  that  I  should  com- 
pare the  MS.  with  the  original  work,  and  suggest  such 
alterations  as  I  might  deem  advisable.  When,  by  and 
by,  it  was  found  that  Mr.  Moore's  professional  occupa- 
tions prevented  him  from  finishing  the  translation  as 
quickly  as  we  all  desired,  we  gladly  accepted  Dr.  Aveling's 
offer  to  undertake  a  portion  of  the  work  ;  at  the  same 
time  Mrs.  Aveling,  Marx's  youngest  daughter,  offered  to 
check  the  quotations  and  to  restore  the  original  text  of 


X  Editors  Preface, 

the  numerous  passages  taken  from  English  authors  and 
Bluebooks  and  translated  by  Marx  into  German.  This 
has  been  done  throughout,  with  but  a  few  unavoidable 
exceptions. 

The  following  portions  of  the  book  have  been  trans- 
lated by  Dr.  Aveling  :  (Ij  Chap'  ^rs  X.  (The  Working 
Day),  and  XI.  (Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus-Value)  ;  (2) 
Part  VI.  (Wages,  comprising  Chapters  XIX.  to  XXII.) ; 
(3)  from  Chapter  XXIV,  Section  4  (Circumstances  that 
&c.)  to  tiie  end  of  the  book,  comprising  the  latter  part 
of  Chapter  XXIV.,  Chapter  XXV.,  and  the  whole  of 
Part  VIII.  (Chapters  XXVL  to  XXXIII.)  ;  (4)  the  two 
Author's  prefaces.  All  the  rest  of  the  book  has  been 
done  by  Mr.  Moore.  While,  thus,  each  of  the  trans- 
lators is  responsible  for  his  share  of  the  work  only,  I 
bear  a  joint  responsibility  for  the  whole. 

The  third  German  edition,  which  has  been  made 
the  basis  of  our  work  throughout,  was  prepared  by 
me,  in  1883,  with  the  assistance  of  notes  left  by  the 
author,  indicating  the  passages  of  the  second  edition 
to  be  replaced  by  designated  passages,  from  the 
French  text  published  in  1873.^  The  alterations  thus 
effected  in  the  text  of  the  second  edition  generally  coin- 
cided with  changes  prescribed  by  Marx  in  a  set  of  MS. 
instructions  for  an  English  translation  that  was  planned, 
about  ten  years  ago,  in  America,  but  abandoned  chiefly  for 
want  of  a  fit  and  proper  translator.  This  MS.  was  placed 
at  our  disposal  by  our  old  friend  Mr.  F.  A.  Sorge  of 
Hoboken  N.J.  It  designates  some  further  interpolations 
from  the  French  edition  ;  but,  being  so  many  years  older 

1  "Le  Capital,"  par  Karl  Marx.  Traduction  de  M.  J.  Roy,  enti^re- 
ment  revisee  par  I'auteur.  Paris.  Lachatre."  This  translation,  especially  in 
the  latter  part  of  the  book,  contains  considerable  alterations  in  and  additions 
to  the  text  of  the  second  German  edition. 


Editors  Preface,  xi 

than  tlie  final  instructions  for  the  third  edition,  I  did  not 
consider  myself  at  liberty  to  make  use  of  it  otherwise 
than  sparingly,  and  chiefly  in  cases  where  it  helped  us 
over  difiiculties.  In  the  same  way,  the  French  text  has 
been  referred  to  in  most  of  the  difficult  passages,  as  an 
indicator  of  what  the  author  himself  was  prepared  to 
sacrifice  wherever  something  of  the  full  import  of  the 
original  had  to  be  sacrificed  in  the  rendering. 

There  is,  however,  one  difficulty  we  could  not  spare 
the  reader  :  the  use  of  certain  terms  in  a  sense  different 
from  what  they  have,  not  only  in  common  life,  but  in 
ordinary  political  economy.  But  this  was  unavoidable. 
Every  new  aspect  of  a  science  involves  a  revolution  in 
the  technical  terms  of  that  science.  This  is  best  shown  by 
chemistry,  where  the  whole  of  the  terminology  is  radically 
changed  about  once  in  twenty  years,  and  where  you  will 
hardly  find  a  single  organic  compound  that  has  not  gone 
through  a  whole  series  of  different  names.  Political 
Economy  has  generally  been  content  to  take,  just  as  they 
were,  the  terms  of  commercial  and  industrial  life,  and  to 
operate  with  them,  entirely  failing  to  see  that  by  so  doing, 
it  confined  itself  within  the  narrow  circle  of  ideas 
expressed  by  those  terms.  Thus,  though  perfectly  aware 
that  both  profits  and  rent  are  but  sub- divisions,  frag- 
ments of  that  unpaid  part  of  the  product  which  the 
labourer  has  to  supply  to  his  employer  (its  first  appro- 
priator,  though  not  its  ultimate  exclusive  owner),  yet 
even  classical  Political  Economy  never  went  beyond 
the  received  notions  of  profits  and  rents,  never  examined 
this  unpaid  part  of  the  product  (called  by  Marx  surplus- 
product)  in  its  integrity  as  a  whole,  and  therefore  never 
arrived  at  a  clear  comprehension,  either  of  its  origin  and 
nature,  or  of  the  laws  that  regulate  the  subsequent  distri- 
bution of  its  value.  Similarly  all  industry,  not  agricultural 


xii  Edito7'''s  Preface, 

or  handicraft,  is  indiscriminately  comprised  in  the  term  of 
manufacture,  and  thereby  the  distinction  is  obliterated  be- 
tween two  great  and  essentially  diJfferent  periods  of  econ- 
omic history:  the  period  of  manufacture  proper,  based  oa 
the  division  of  manual  labour,  and  the  period  of  modern 
industry  based  on  machinery.  It  is,  however,  self-evi- 
dent that  a  theory  which  views  modem  capitalist  pro- 
duction as  a  mere  passing  stage  in  the  economic  history 
of  mankind,  must  make  use  of  terms  different  from  those 
habitual  to  writers  who  look  upon  that  form  of  produc- 
tion as  imperishable  and  final. 

A  word  respecting  the  author's  method  of  quoting 
may  not  be  out  of  place.  In  the  majority  of  cases,  the 
quotations  serve,  in  the  usual  way,  as  documentary  evi- 
dence in  support  of  assertions  made  in  the  text.  But  in  many 
instances,  passages  from  economic  writers  are  quoted  in 
order  to  indicate  when,  where,  and  by  whom  a  certain 
proposition  was  for  the  first  time  clearly  enunciated. 
This  is  done  in  cases  where  the  proposition  quoted  is  of  im- 
portance as  being  a  more  or  less  adequate  expression  of  the 
conditions  of  social  production  and  exchange  prevalent 
at  the  time,  and  quite  irrespective  of  Marx's  recognition, 
or  otherwise,  of  its  general  validity.  These  quotations, 
therefore,  supplement  the  text  by  a  running  commentary 
taken  from  the  history  of  the  science. 

Our  translation  comprises  the  first  book  of  the  work 
only.  But  this  first  book  is  in  a  great  measure  a  whole 
in  itself,  and  has  for  twenty  years  ranked  as  an  inde- 
pendent work.  The  second  book,  edited  in  German 
by  me,  in  1883,  is  decidedly  incomplete  without  the  third, 
which  cannot  be  published  before  the  end  of  1887. 
When  Book  III.  has  been  brought  out  in  the  original 
German,  it  will  then  be  soon  enough  to  think  about 
preparing  an  English  edition  of  both. 


Editor's  Preface,  xiii 

**  Das  Kapital "  is  often  called,  on  the  Continent, 
"  the  Bible  of  the  working  class."  That  the  conclusions 
arrived  at  in  this  work  are  daily  more  and  more  becoming 
the  fundamental  principles  of  the  great  working  class 
movement,  not  only  in  Germany  and  Switzerland,  but  in 
France,  in  Holland  and  Belgium,  in  America,  and  even 
in  Italy  and  Spain ;  that  everywhere  the  working  class 
more  and  more  recognises,  in  these  conclusions,  the  most 
adequate  expression  of  its  condition  and  of  its  aspirations, 
nobody  acquainted  with  that  movement  will  deny. 
And  in  England,  too,  the  theories  of  Marx,  even  at  this 
moment,  exercise  a  powerful  influence  upon  the  socialist 
movement  which  is  spreading  in  the  ranks  of  "  cultured" 
people  no  less  than  in  those  of  the  working  class.  But 
that  is  not  all.  The  time  is  rapidly  approaching  when 
a  thorough  examination  of  England's  economic  position 
will  impose  itself  as  an  irresistible  national  necessity.  The 
working  of  the  industrial  system  of  this  country,  impos- 
sible without  a  constant  and  rapid  extension  of  pro- 
duction, and  therefore  of  markets,  is  coming  to  a  dead 
stop.  Free  trade  has  exhausted  its  resources ;  even 
Manchester  doubts  this  its  quondam  economic  gospel.^ 
Foreign  industry,  rapidly  developing,  stares  English  pro- 
duction in  the  face  everywhere,  not  only  in  protected,  but 
also  in  neutral  markets,  and  even  on  this  side  of  the 
Channel.  While  the  productive  power  increases  in  a 
geometric,  the  extension  of  markets  proceeds  at  best  in 
an  arithmetic  ratio.     The  decennial  cycle  of  stagnation, 

1  At  the  quarterly  meeting  of  the  Manchester  Chamber  of  Commerce, 
held  this  afternoon,  a  warm  discussion  took  place  on  the  subject  of  Free 
Trade.  A  resolution  was  moved  to  the  effect  that  "  having  waited  in  vain 
40  years  for  other  nations  to  follow  the  Free  Trade  example  of  England, 
this  Chamber  thinks  the  time  has  now  arrived  to  reconsider  that  position." 
The  resolution  was  rejected  by  a  majority  of  one  only,  the  figures  being 
21  for,  and  22  against. — Evening  Standard,  Nov.  1,  1886. 


xiv  Editor  s  Preface. 

prosperity,  over-production  and  crisis,  ever  recurrent 
from  1825  to  1867,  seems  indeed  to  have  run  its  course  ; 
but  only  to  land  us  in  the  slough  of  despond  of  a  per- 
manent and  chronic  depression.  The  sighed-for  period 
of  prosperity  will  not  come  ;  as  often  as  we  seem  to  per- 
ceive its  heralding  symptoms,  so  often  do  they  again 
vanish  into  air.  Meanwhile,  each  succeeding  winter  brings 
up  afresh  the  great  question,  "what  to  do  with  the 
unemployed  ;  "  but  while  the  number  of  the  unemployed 
keeps  swelling  from  year  to  year,  there  is  nobody  to 
answer  that  question  ;  and  we  can  almost  calculate  the 
moment  when  the  unemployed  losing  patience,  will 
take  their  own  fate  into  their  own  hands.  Surely,  at  such 
a  moment,  the  voice  ought  to  be  heard  of  a  man  whose 
whole  theory  is  the  result  of  a  life-long  study  of  the 
economic  history  and  condition  of  England,  and  whom 
that  study  led  to  the  conclusion  that,  at  least  in  Europe, 
England  is  the  only  country  where  the  inevitable  social 
revolution  might  be  effected  entirely  by  peaceful  and 
legal  means.  He  certainly  never  forgot  to  add  that  he 
hardly  expected  the  English  ruling  classes  to  submit, 
without  a  "  pro-slavery  rebellion,"  to  this  peaceful  and 
legal  revolution. 

FREDERICK  ENGELS. 


November  5,  1886. 


AUTHOR'S  PREFACES. 


I.- — T  O     THE     FIRST     EDITION. 

THE  work,  the  first  volume  of  wbicli  I  now  submit 
to  the  public,  forms  the  continuation  of  my  ''  Zur 
Kritik  der  Politischen  Oekonomie  "  (A  contribution  to 
the  criticism  of  Political  Economy)  published  in  1859. 
The  long  pause  between  the  first  part  and  the  continu- 
ation is  due  to  an  illness  of  many  years'  duration  that 
again  and  again  interrupted  my  work. 

The  substance  of  that  earlier  work  is  summarised  in 
the  first  three  chapters  of  this  volume.  This  is  done 
not  merely  for  the  sake  of  connection  and  completeness. 
The  presentation  of  the  subject-matter  is  improved.  As 
far  as  circumstances  in  any  way  permit,  many  points 
only  hinted  at  in  the  earlier  book  are  here  worked  out 
more  fully,  whilst,  conversely,  points  worked  out  fully 
there  are  only  touched  upon  in  this  volume.  The 
sections  on  the  history  of  the  theories  of  value  and  of 
money  are  now,  of  course,  left  out  altogether.  The 
reader  of  the  earlier  work  will  find,  however,  in  the 
notes  to  the  first  chapter  additional  sources  of  reference 
relative  to  the  history  of  those  theories. 

Every  beginning  is  difficult,  holds  in  all  sciences.  To 
understand  the  first  chapter,  especially  the  section  that 
contains  the  analysis  of  commodities,  will,  therefore,  pre- 
sent the  greatest  difficulty.     That  which  concerns  more 


xvi  Authors  Prefaces. 

especially  the  analysis  of  the  substance  of  value  and  the 
magnitude  of  value,  I  have,  as  much  as  it  was  possible, 
popularised/  The  value-form,  whose  fully  developed 
shape  is  the  money  form,  is  very  elementary  and  simple. 
Nevertheless,  the  human  mind  has  for  more  than  2000 
years  sought  in  vain  to  get  to  the  bottom  of  it,  whilst  on 
the  other  hand,  to  the  successful  analysis  of  much  more 
composite  and  complex  forms,  there  has  been  at  least  an 
approximation.  Why?  Because  the  body,  as  an  organic 
whole,  is  more  easy  of  study  than  are  the  cells  of  that 
body.  In  the  analysis  of  economic  forms,  moreover, 
neither  microscopes  nor  chemical  reagents  are  of  use. 
The  force  of  abstraction  must  replace  both.  But  in 
bourgeois  society  the  commodity-form  of  the  product  of 
labour — or  the  value-form  of  the  commodity — is  the 
economic  cell-form.  To  the  superficial  observer,  the 
analysis  of  these  forms  seems  to  turn  upon  minutiae.  It 
does  in  fact  deal  with  minutiae,  but  they  are  of  the  same 
order  as  those  dealt  with  in  microscopic  anatomy. 

With  the  exception  of  the  section  on  value-form, 
therefore,  this  volume  cannot  stand  accused  on  the  score 
of  difficulty.  I  pre-suppose,  of  course,  a  reader  who  is 
willing  to  learn  something  new  and  therefore  to  think 
for  himself. 

The    physicist   either   observes    physical   phenomena 

''  This  is  the  more  necessary,  as  even  the  section  of  Ferdinand  Lassalle's 
work  against  Schulze-Delitzsch,  in  which  he  professes  to  give  "the  intel- 
lectual quintessence  "  of  my  explanations  on  these  subjects,  contains  im- 
portant mistakes.  If  Ferdinand  Lassalle  has  borrowed  almost  literally 
from  my  writings,  and  without  any  acknowledgment,  all  the  general 
theoretical  propositions  in  his  economic  works,  e.q,^  those  on  the  historical 
character  of  capital,  on  the  connection  between  the  conditions  of  produc- 
tion and  the  mode  of  production,  &c.,  &c.  even  to  the  terminology  created 
by  me,  this  may  perhaps  be  due  to  purposes  of  propaganda.  I  am  here, 
of  course,  not  speaking  of  his  detailed  working  out  and  application  of  these 
propositions,  with  which  I  have  nothing  to  do. 


Author's  Prefaces,  xvii 

where  they  occur  in  their  most  typical  form  and  most 
free  from  disturbing  influence,  or,  wherever  possible,  he 
makes  experiments  under  conditions  that  assure  the 
occurrence  of  the  phenomenon  in  its  normality.  In  this 
work  I  have  to  examine  the  capitalist  mode  of  produc- 
tion, and  the  conditions  of  production  and  exchange  cor- 
responding to  that  mode.  Up  to  the  present  time,  their 
classic  ground  is  England.  That  is  the  reason  why  Eng- 
land is  used  as  the  chief  illustration  in  the  development 
of  my  theoretical  ideas.  If,  however,  the  German  reader 
shrugs  his  shoulders  at  the  condition  of  the  English  in- 
dustrial and  agricultural  labourers,  or  in  optimist  fashion 
comforts  himself  with  the  thought  that  in  Germany 
things  are  not  nearly  so  bad ;  I  must  plainly  tell  him, 
^'  De  te  fabula  narratur  !  " 

Intrinsically,  it  is  not  a  question  of  the  higher  or 
lower  degree  of  development  of  the  social  antagonisms 
that  result  from  the  natural  laws  of  capitalist  production. 
It  is  a  question  of  these  laws  themselves,  of  these 
tendencies  working  with  iron  necessity  towards  inevit- 
able results.  The  country  that  is  more  developed  indus- 
trially only  shows,  to  the  less  developed,  the  image  of 
its  own  future. 

But  apart  from  this.  Where  capitalist  production  is 
fully  naturalised  among  the  Germans  (for  instance,  in  the 
factories  proper)  the  condition  of  things  is  much  worse 
than  in  England,  because  the  counterpoise  of  the  Factory 
Acts  is  wanting.  In  all  other  spheres,  we,  like  all  the 
rest  of  Continental  Western  Europe,  suffer  not  only  from 
the  development  of  capitalist  production,  but  also  from 
the  incompleteness  of  that  development.  Alongside  of 
modem  evils,  a  whole  series  of  inherited  evils  oppress 
us,  arising  from  the  passive  survival  of  antiquated  modes 
of  production,  with  their  inevitable  train  of  social  and 


xviii  Author s  Prefaces, 

political  anachronisms.  We  suffer  not  only  from  the 
living,  but  from  the  dead.     Le  mort  saisit  le  vif ! 

The  social  statistics  of  Germany  and  the  rest  of  Con- 
tinental Western  Europe  are,  in  comparison  with  those 
of  England,  wretchedly  compiled.  But  they  raise  the 
veil  just  enough  to  let  us  catch  a  glimpse  of  the  Medusa 
head  behind  it.  We  should  be  appalled  at  the  state  of 
things  at  home,  if,  as  in  England,  our  governments  and 
parliaments  appointed  periodically  commissions  of  en- 
quiry into  economic  conditions;  if  these  commissions  were 
armed  with  the  same  plenary  powers  to  get  at  the  trath ; 
if  it  was  possible  to  find  for  this  purpose  men  as  competent, 
as  free  from  partisanship  and  respect  of  persons  as  are 
the  English  factory -inspectors,  her  medical  reporters 
on  public  health,  her  commissioners  of  enquiry  into  the 
exploitation  of  women  and  children,  into  housing  and 
food.  Perseus  wore  a  magic  cap  that  the  monsters 
he  hunted  down  might  not  see  him.  We  draw  the 
magic  cap  down  over  eyes  and  ears  as  a  make-believe 
that  there  are  no  monsters. 

Let  us  not  deceive  ourselves  on  this.  As  in  the  18th 
century,  the  American  war  of  independence  sounded  the 
tocsin  for  the  European  middle-class,  so  in  the  19  th  century, 
the  American  civil  war  sounded  it  for  the  European 
working-class.  In  England  the  progress  of  social  dis- 
integration is  palpable.  When  it  has  reached  a  certain 
point,  it  must  re-act  on  the  continent.  There  it  will  take 
a  form  more  brutal  or  more  humane,  according  to  the 
degree  of  develop ment  of  the  working-class  itself.  Apart 
from  higher  motives,  therefore,  their  own  most  impor- 
tant interests  dictate  to  the  classes  that  are  for  the 
nonce  the  ruling  ones,  the  removal  of  all  legally  remov- 
able hindrances  to  the  free  development  of  the  working 
class.     For  this  reason,  as  well  as  others,  I  have  given 


Author  s  Prefaces.  xix 

so  large  a  space  in  this  volume  to  the  history,  the  de- 
tails, and  the  results  of  English  factory  legislation.  One 
nation  can  and  should  learn  from  others.  And  even 
when  a  society  has  got  upon  the  right  track  for  the  dis- 
coverv  of  the  natural  laws  of  its  movement — and  it  is  the 
ultimate  aim  of  this  work,  to  lay  l^are  the  economic  law 
of  motion  of  modern  society — it  can  neither  clear  by 
bold  leaps,  nor  remove  by  legal  enactmejits,  the  obstacles 
offered  by  the  successive  phases  of  its  normal  develop- 
ment.    But  it  can  shorten  and  lessen  the  birth-pangs. 

To  prevent  possible  misunderstanding,  a  word.  I 
paint  the  capitalist  and  the  landlord  in  no  sense  couleur- 
de  rose.  But  here  individuals  are  dealt  with  only  in  so  far 
as  they  are  the  personifications  of  economic  categories, 
embodiments  of  particular  class-relations  and  class- 
interests.  My  stand-point,  from  which  the  evolution  of 
the  economic  formation  of  society  is  viewed  as  a  process 
of  natural  history,  can  less  than  any  other  make  the 
individual  responsible  for  relations  whose  creature  he 
socially  remains,  however  much  he  may  subjectively 
raise  himself  above  them. 

In  the  domain  of  Political  Economy,  free  scientific 
enquiry  meets  not  merely  the  same  enemies  as  in  all 
other  domains.  The  peculiar  nature  of  the  material  it 
deals  with,  summons  as  foes  into  the  field  of  battle  the 
most  violent,  mean  and  malignant  passions  of  the  human 
breast,  the  Furies  of  private  interest.  The  English  Estab- 
lished Church,  e.g.^  will  more  readily  pardon  an  attack 
on  38  of  its  39  articles  than  on  A  of  its  income.  Now- 
adays  atheism  itself  is  culpa  levis,  as  compared  with 
criticism  of  existing  property  relations.  Nevertheless, 
there  is  an  unmistakable  advance.  I  refer,  e.g.,  to  the 
bluebook  published  within  the  last  few  weeks  :  '*  Corre- 
spondence with  Her  Majesty's  Missions  Abroad,  regard- 


XX  Authors  Prefaces. 

ing  Industrial  Questions  and  Trades'  Unions."  The 
representatives  of  the  English  Crown  in  foreign  countries 
there  declare  in  so  many  words  that  in  Germany,  in 
France,  to  be  brief,  in  all  the  civilised  states  of  the 
European  continent,  a  radical  change  in  the  existing 
relations  between  capital  and  labour  is  as  evident  and 
inevitable  as  in  England.  At  the  same  time,  on  the 
other  side  of  the  Atlantic  Ocean,  Mr.  Wade,  vice-presi- 
dent of  the  United  States,  declared  in  public  meetings 
that,  after  the  abolition  of  slavery,  a  radical  change  of 
the  relations  of  capital  and  of  property  in  land  is  next 
upon  the  order  of  the  day.  These  are  signs  of  the 
times,  not  to  be  hidden  by  purple  mantles  or  black 
cassocks.  They  do  not  signify  that  to-morrow  a  miracle 
will  happen.  They  show  that,  within  the  ruling-classes 
themselves,  a  foreboding  is  dawning,  that  the  present 
society  is  no  solid  crystal,  but  an  organism  capable  of 
change,  and  is  constantly  changing. 

The  second  volume  of  this  work  will  treat  of  the  pro- 
cess of  the  circulation  of  capital^  (Book  II.),  and  of  the 
varied  forms  assumed  by  capital  in  the  course  of  its 
development  (Book  III.),  the  third  and  last  volume 
(Book  IV.),  the  history  of  the  theory. 

Every  opinion  based  on  scientific  criticism  I  welcome. 
As  to  the  prejudices  of  so-called  public  opinion,  to  which 
I  have  never  made  concessions,  now  as  aforetime  the 
maxim  of  the  great  Florentine  is  mine  : 

"  Segui  il  tuo  corso,.e  lascia  dir  le  genti." 

KARL  MARX. 

London,  July  25,  1867. 

"•  On  p.  570  the  author  explains  what  he  comprises  under  this  head. 


Author  s  Prefaces,  xxi 

n. TO   THE    SECOND    EDITION. 

To  the  present  moment  Political  Economy,  in  Ger- 
many, is  a  foreign  science.  Gustav  von  Glilich  in  his 
"  Historical  description  of  Commerce,  Industry,"  &c.,  ^ 
especially  in  the  two  first  volumes  published  in  1830, 
has  examined  at  length. the  historical  circumstances  that 
prevented,  in  Germany,  the  development  of  the  capitalist 
mode  of  production,  and  consequently  the  development, 
in  that  country,  of  modern  bourgeois  society.  Thus  the 
soil  whence  Political  Economy  springs  was  wanting. 
This  '' science"  had  to  be  imported  from  England  and 
France  as  a  ready-made  article  ;  its  German  professors 
remained  schoolboys.  The  theoretical  expression  of  a 
foreign  reality  was  turned,  in  their  hands,  into  a  col- 
lection of  dogmas,  interpreted  by  them  in  terms  of  the 
petty  trading  world  around  them,  and  therefore  mis- 
interpreted. The  feeling  of  scientific  impotence,  a 
feeling  not  wholly  to  be  repressed,  and  the  uneasy  con- 
sciousness of  having  to  touch  a  subject  in  reality  foreign 
to  them,  was  but  imperfectly  concealed,  either  under  a 
parade  of  literary  and  historical  erudition,  or  by  an 
admixture  of  extraneous  material,  borrowed  from  the  so- 
called  "  Kameral "  sciences,  a  medley  of  smatterings, 
through  whose  purgatory  the  hopeless  candidate  for  the 
German  bureaucracy  has  to  pass. 

Since  1848  capitalist  production  has  developed  rapidly 
in  Germany,  and  at  the  present  time  it  is  in  the  full 
bloom  of  speculation  and  swindling.  But  fate  is  still 
unpropitious  to  our  professional  economists.  At  the 
time  when  they  were  able  to  deal  with  Political  Economy 
■in  a  straightforward  fashion,  modem  economic  conditions 

''  Geschichtliche  Darstellung  des  Handels,  der  Gewerbe  und  des  Acker- 
baus,  &c.,  von  Gustav  von  Giilich.     5  vols.,  Jena,  1830-45. 


xxii  Authors  Prefaces, 

did  not  actually  exist  in  Germany.  And  as  soon  as  these 
conditions  did  come  into  existence,  they  did  so  under  cir- 
cumstances that  no  longer  allowed  of  their  being  really 
and  impartially  investigated  within  the  bounds  of  the 
bourgeois  horizon.  In  so  far  as  Political  Economy 
remains  within  that  horizon,  in  so  far,  i.e.^  as  the  capita- 
list regime  is  looked  upon  as  the  absolutely  final  form  of 
social  production,  instead  of  as  a  passing  historical  phase 
of  its  evolution,  Political  Economy  can  remain  a  science 
only  so  long  as  the  class -struggle  is  latent  or  manifests 
itself  only  in  isolated  and  sporadic  phenomena. 

Let  us  take  England.  Its  political  economy  belongs 
to  the  period  in  which  the  class-struggle  was  as  yet  un- 
developed. Its  last  great  representative,  Ricardo,  in 
the  end,  consciously  makes  the  antagonism  of  class- 
interests,  of  wages  and  profits,  of  profits  and  rent,  the 
starting-point  of  his  investigations,  naively  taking  this 
antagonism  for  a  social  law  of  nature.  But  by  this 
start  the  science  of  bourgeois  economy  had  reached  the 
limits  beyond  which  it  could  not  pass.  Already  in  the 
lifetime  of  Ricardo,  and  in  opposition  to  him,  it  was  met 
by  criticism,  in  the  person  of  Sismondi.^ 

The  succeeding  period,  from  1820  to  1830,  was 
notable  in  England  for  scientific  activity  in  the  domain 
of  Political  Economy.  It  was  the  time  as  well  of  the 
vulgarising  and  extending  of  Ricardo's  theory,  as  of  the 
contest  of  that  theory  with  the  old  school.  Splendid 
tournaments  were  held.  What  was  done  then,  is  little 
known  to  the  Continent  generally,  because  the  polemic 
is  for  the  most  part  scattered  through  articles  in  reviews, 
occasional  literature  and  pamphlets.  The  unprejudiced 
character   of    this    polemic — ^^although    the    theory   of 

T  See  my  work  *'  Zur  Kritik,  &c.,"  p.  39. 


Author  s  Pre/aces,  xxiii 

Ricardo  already  serves,  ia  exceptional  cases,  as  a  weapon 
of  attack  upon  bourgeois  economy — ^is  explained  by  the 
circumstances  of  the  time.  On  the  one  hand,  modern 
industry  itself  was  only  just  emerging  from  the  age  of 
childhood,  as  is  shown  by  the  fact  that  with  the  crisis 
of  1825  it  for  the  first  time  opens  the  periodic  cycle  of 
its  modern  life.  On  the  other  hand,  the  class- struo^de 
between  capital  and  labour  is  forced  into  the  background, 
politically  by  the  discord  between  the  governments  and 
the  feudal  aristocracy  gathered  around  the  Holy  Alliance 
on  the  one  hand,  and  the  popular  masses,  led  by  the  bour- 
geoisie on  the  other;  economically  by  the  quarrel  between 
industrial  capital  and  aristocratic  landed  property — a 
quarrel  that  in  France  was  concealed  by  the  opposition 
between  small  and  large  landed  property,  and  that 
in  England  broke  out  openly  after  the  Corn  Laws.  The 
literature  of  Political  Economy  in  England  at  this  time 
calls  to  mind  the  stormy  forward  movement  in  France 
after  Dr.  Quesnay's  death,  but  only  as  a  Saint  Martin's 
summer  reminds  us  of  spring.  With  the  year  1830 
came  the  decisive  crisis. 

In  France  and  in  England  the  bourgeoisie  had  con- 
quered political  power.  Thenceforth,  the  class-struggle, 
practically  as  well  as  theoretically,  took  on  more  and 
more  outspoken  and  threatening  forms.  It  sounded  the 
knell  of  scientific  bourgeois  economy.  It  was  thenceforth 
no  longer  a  question,  whether  this  theorem  or  that  was 
true,  but  whether  it  was  useful  to  capital  or  harmful, 
expedient  or  inexpedient,  politically  dangerous  or  not. 
In  place  of  disinterested  enquirers,  there  were  hired  prize- 
fighters ;  in  place  of  genuine  scientific  research,  the  bad 
conscience  and  the  evil  intent  of  apologetic.  Still,  even 
the  obtrusive  pamphlets  with  which  the  Anti-Corn  Law 
League,  led  by  the  manufacturers  Cobden  and  Bright^ 


xxiv  Author^s  Prefaces, 

deluged  the  world,  have  a  historic  interest,  if  no  scientific 
one,  on  account  of  their  polemic  against  the  landed  aris- 
tocracy. But  siace  then  the  Free  Trade  legislation, 
inaugurated  by  Sir  Robert  Peel,  has  deprived  vulgar 
economy  of  this  its  last  sting. 

The  Continental  revolution  of  1848-9  also  had  its  re- 
action in  England.  Men  who  still  claimed  some  scien- 
tific standing  and  aspired  to  be  something  more  than 
mere  sophists  and  sycophants  of  the  ruling-classes,  tried 
to  harmonise  the  Political  Economy  of  capital  with  the 
claims,  no  longer  to  be  ignored,  of  the  proletariat. 
Hence  a  shallow  syncretism,  of  which  John  Stuart  Mill 
is  the  best  representative.  It  is  a  declaration  of  bank- 
ruptcy by  bourgeois  economy,  an  event  on  which  the 
great  Russian  scholar  and  critic,  N.  Tschernyschewsky, 
has  thrown  the  light  of  a  master  mind  in  his  ''  Outlines 
of  Political  Economy  according  to  Mill." 

In  Germany,  therefore,  the  capitalist  mode  of  produc- 
tion came  to  a  head,  after  its  antagonistic  character  had 
already,  in  France  and  England,  shown  itself  in  a  fierce 
strife  of  classes.  And  meanwhile,  moreover,  the  German 
proletariat  had  attained  a  much  more  clear  class-con- 
sciousness than  the  German  bourgeoisie.  Thus,  at  the 
very  moment  when  a  bourgeois  science  of  political 
economy  seemed  at  last  possible  in  Germany,  it  had  in 
reality  again  become  impossible. 

Under  these  circumstances  its  professors  fell  into  two 
groups.  The  one  set,  prudent,  practical  business  folk, 
flocked  to  the  banner  of  Bastiat,  the  most  superficial 
and  therefore  the  most  adequate  representative  of  the 
apologetic  of  vulgar  economy ;  the  other,  proud  of  the 
professorial  dignity  of  their  science,  followed  John 
Stuart  Mill  in  his  attempt  to  reconcile  irreconcilables. 
Just  as  in  the  classical  time  of  bourgeois  economy,  so 


Author's  Prefaces.  xxv 

also  in  the  time  of  its  decline,  the  Germans  remained 
mere  schoolboys,  imitators  and  followers,  petty  retailers 
and  hawkers  in  the  service  of  the  great  foreign  whole- 
sale concern. 

The  peculiar  historic  development  of  German  society 
therefore  forbids,  in  that  country,  all  original  work  in 
bourgeois  economy ;  but  not  the  criticism  of  that 
economy.  So  far  as  such  criticism  represents  a  class,  it 
can  only  represent  the  class  whose  vocation  in  history 
is  the  overthrow  of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production 
and  the  final  abolition  of  all  classes — the  proletariat. 

The  learned  and  unlearned  spokesmen  of  the  German 
bourgeoisie  tried  at  first  to  kill  "Das  Kapital  "  by  silence, 
as  they  had  managed  to  do  with  my  earlier  writings.  As 
soon  as  they  found  that  these  tactics  no  longer  fited  in 
with  the  conditions  of  the  time,  they  wrote,  under  pretence 
of  criticising  my  book,  prescriptions  ''  for  the  tranquillisa- 
tion  of  the  bourgeois  mind."  But  they  found  in  the 
workers'  press — see,  e.g,^  Joseph  Dietzgen's  articles  in 
the  "  Volksstaat  " — antagonists  stronger  than  themselves, 
Ko  whom  (down  to  this  very  day)  they  owe  a  reply. ^ 

An  excellent  Eussian  translation  of  "  Das  Kapital  "  ap- 

''  The  mealy-mouthed  babblers  of  German  vulgar  economy  fell  foul  of 
the  style  of  my  book.  No  one  can  feel  the  literary  shortcomings  in  "  Das 
Kapital  "  more  strongly  than  I  myself.  Yet  I  will  for  the  benefit  and  the 
enjoyment  of  these  gentlemen  and  their  public  quote  in  this  connection 
one  English  and  one  Russian  notice.  The  "  Saturday  Review,"  always 
hostile  to  my  views,  said  in  its  notice  of  the  first  edition  :  "  The  presenta- 
tion of  the  subject  invests  the  driest  economic  questions  with  a  certain 
peculiar  charm."  The  '*  St.  Petersburg  Journal  "  (Sankt-Peterburgskie 
Viedomosti),  in  its  issue  of  April  20,  1872,  says  :  "  The  presentation  of 
the  subject,  with  the  exception  of  one  or  two  exceptionally  special  parts, 
is  distinguished  by  its  comprehensibility  by  fche  general  reader,  its  clear- 
ness, and,  in  spite  of  the  scientific  intricacy  of  the  subject,  by  an  unusual 
liveliness.  In  this  respect  the  author  in  no  way  resembles  .  .  .  the 
majority  of  German  scholars  who  .  .  .  write  their  books  in  a  language  so 
dry  and  obscure  that  the  heads  of  ordinary  mortals  are  cracked  by  it." 


xxvi  Author  s  Prefaces, 

peared  in  the  spring  of  1872.  The  edition  of  3000 
copies  is  already  neariy  exhausted.  As  early  as  1871, 
A.  Sieber,  Professor  of  Political  Economy  in  the  Univer- 
sity of  Kiev,  in  his  work  "  David  Ricardo's  Theory  of 
Value  and  of  Capital,"  referred  to  my  theory  of  value,  of 
money  and  of  capital,  as  in  its  fundamentals  a  necessary 
sequel  to  the  teaching  of  Smith  and  Ricardo.  That 
which  astonishes  the  Western  European  in  the  reading 
of  this  excellent  work,  is  the  author's  consistent  and  firm 
grasp  of  the  purely  theoretical  position. 

That  the  method  employed  in  "  D^s  Kapital "  has 
been  little  understood,  is  shown  by  the  various  concep- 
tions, contradictory  one  to  another,  that  have  been 
formed  of  it. 

Thus  the  Paris  Revue  Posiviste  reproaches  me  in  that, 
on  the  one  hand,  I  treat  economics  metaphysically,  and 
on  the  other  hand — imagine  ! — confine  myself  to  the 
mere  critical  analysis  of  actual  facts,  instead  of  writing 
receipts  (Comtist  ones?)  for  the  cook-shops  of  the  future. 
In  answer  to  the  reproach  in  re  metaphysics.  Professor 
Sieber  has  it :  "  In  so  far  as  it  deals  with  actual  theory, 
the  method  of  Marx  is  the  deductive  method  of  the 
whole  English  school,  a  school  whose  failings  and  virtues 
are  common  to  the  best  theoretic  economists."  M.  Block 
— "Les  theoriciens  du  socialisme  en  Allemagne,  Extrait 
du  Journal  des  Economistes,  Juillet  et  AoM  1872  " — 
makes  the  discovery  that  my  method  is  analytic  and 
says :  ^'  Par  cet  ouvrage  M.  Marx  se  classe  parmi  les 
esprits  analytiques  les  plus  6minents."  German  reviews, 
of  course,  shriek  out  at  "  Hegelian  sophistics."  The 
European  Messenger  of  St.  Petersburg,  in  an  article  deal- 
ing exclusively  with  the  method  of  **  Das  Kapital" 
(May  number,  1872,  pp.  427-436),  finds  my  method  of 
enquiry  severely  realistic,  but  my  method  of  presentation, 


Author  s  Prefaces,  xxvii 

unfortunately,  German-dialectical.  It  says:  ''At  first 
sight,  if  the  judgment  is  based  on  the  external  form  of 
the  presentation  of  the  subject,  Marx  is  the  most  ideal 
of  ideal  philosophers,  always  in  the  German,  i.e.^  the 
bad  sense  of  the  word.  But  in  point  of  fact  he  is 
infinitely  more  realistic  than  all  his  fore-runners  in  the 
work  of  economic  criticism.  He  can  in  no  sense  be 
called  an  idealist."  I  cannot  answer  the  writer  better 
than  by  aid  of  a  few  extracts  from  his  own  criticism, 
which  may  interest  some  of  my  readers  to  whom  the 
Russian  original  is  inaccessible. 

After  a  quotation  from  the  preface  to  my  "  Criticism 
of  Political  Economy,"  Berlin,  1859,  pp.  4-7,  where  I  dis- 
cuss the  materialistic  basis  of  my  method,  the  writer  goes 
on :  ^'  The  one  thing  which  is  of  moment  to  Marx,  is  to 
find  the  law  of  the  phenomena  with  whose  investigation  he 
is  concerned ;  and  not  only  is  that  law  of  moment  to  him, 
which  governs  these  phenomena,  in  so  far  as  they  have 
a  definite  form  and  mutual  connection  within  a  given 
historical  period.  Of  still  greater  moment  to  him  is 
the  law  of  their  variation,  of  their  development,  ^.^.,  of 
their  transition  from  one  form  into  another,  from  one 
series  of  connections  into  a  different  one.  This  law  once 
discovered,  he  investigates  in  detail  the  effects  in  which 
it  manifests  itself  in  social  life.  Consequently,  Marx 
only  troubles  himself  about  one  thing ;  to  show,  by 
rigid  scientific  investigation,  the  necessity  of  successive 
determinate  orders  of  social  conditions,  and  to  establish, 
as  impartially  as  possible,  the  facts  that  serve  him  for 
fundamental  starting  points.  For  this  it  is  quite  enough, 
if  he  proves,  at  the  same  time,  both  the  necessity  of 
the  present  order  of  things,  and  the  necessity  of  another 
order  into  which  the  first  must  inevitably  pass  over ; 
and  this  all  the  same,  whether  men  believe  or  do  not 


xxviii  Author's  Prefaces, 

believe  it,  whether  they  are  conscious  or  unconscious  of 
it.      Marx   treats    the   social   movement   as   a   process 
of  natural  history,  governed  by  laws  not  only  indepen- 
dent of  human  will,  consciousness  and  intelligence,  but 
rather,  on  the  contrary,  determining  that  will,  conscious- 
ness and  intelligence.  .  .  .  If  in  the  history  of  civilisa- 
tion the  conscious  element  plays  a  part  so  subordinate, 
then  it  is  self-evident  that  a  critical*  inquiry  whose  sub- 
ject-matter is  civilisation,  can,  less  than  anything  else, 
have  for  its  basis  any  form  of,  or  any  result  of,  conscious- 
ness.     That   is   to   say,    that   not    the   idea,    but   the 
material  phenomenon  alone  can  serve  as  its  starting- 
point.     Such  an  inquiry  will  confine  itself  to  the  con- 
frontation and  the  comparison  of  a  fact,  not  with  ideas, 
but  with  another  fact.     For  this  inquiry,  the  one  thing 
of  moment  is,  that  both  facts  be  investigated  as  accur- 
ately as  possible,  and  that  they  actually  form,  each  with 
respect  to  the  other,  diiFerent  momenta  of  an  evolution ; 
but  most  important  of  all  is  the  rigid  analysis  of  the 
series  of  successions,  of  the  sequences  and  concatenations 
in  which  the  dijfferent  stages  of  such  an  evolution  pre- 
sent themselves.      But  it  will  be  said,  the  general  laws 
of  economic   life   are   one  and   the   same,   no   matter 
whether  they  are  applied  to  the  present  or  the  past. 
This  Marx  directly  denies.      According   to  him,  such 
abstract  laws  do  not  exist.      On  the  contrary,  in  his 
opinion  every  historical  period  has  laws  of  Its  own.  .  .  . 
As  soon  as  society  has  outlived  a  given  period  of  develop- 
ment, and  is  passing  over  from  one  given  stage  to  another, 
it  begins  to  be  subject  also  to  other  laws.     In  a  word, 
economic  life  offers  ns  a  phenomenon  analogous  to  the 
history  of  evolution  in  other  branches  of  biology.     The 
old  economists  misunderstood  the  nature  of  economic 
laws  when  they  likened  them  to  the  laws  of  physics  and 


Author  s  Prefaces. 


XXIX 


chemistry.  A  more  thorough  analysis  of  phenomena 
shows  that  social  organisms  differ  among  themselves  as 
fundamentally  as  plants  or  animals.  Nay,  one  and  the 
same  phenomenon  falls  under  quite  different  laws  in 
consequence  of  the  different  structure  of  those  organisms 
as  a  whole,  of  the  variations  of  their  individual  organs, 
of  the  different  conditions  in  which  those  organs  function, 
i&c.  Marx,  e.g.^  denies  that  the  law  of  population  is  the 
same  at  all  times  and  in  all  places.  He  asserts,  on  the 
contrary,  that  every  stage  of  development  has  its  own 
law  of  population.  .  .  .  With  the  varying  degree  of 
development  of  productive  power,  social  conditions  and 
the  laws  governing  them  vary  too.  Whilst  Marx  sets 
himself  the  task  of  following  and  explaining  from  this 
point  of  view  the  economic  system  established  by  the 
sway  of  capital,  he  is  only  formulating,  in  a  strictly 
scientific  manner,  the  aim  that  every  accurate  investiga- 
tion into  economic  life  must  have.  The  scientific  value  of 
such  an  inquiry  lies  in  the  disclosing  of  the  special  laws 
that  regulate  the  origin,  existence,  development,  death 
of  a  given  social  organism  and  its  replacement  by 
another  and  higher  one.  And  it  is  this  value  that,  in 
point  of  fact,  Marxs  book  has." 

Whilst  the  writer  pictures  what  he  takes  to  be 
actually  my  method,  in  this  striking  and  [as  far  as  con- 
cerns my  own  application  of  it]  generous  way,  what 
else  is  he  picturing  but  the  dialectic  method  ? 

Of  course  the  method  of  presentation  must  differ  in  form 
from  that  of  inquiry.  The  latter  has  to  appropriate 
the  material  in  detail,  to  analyse  its  different  forms  of 
development,  to  trace  out  their  inner  connection.  Only 
after  this  work  is  done,  can  the  actual  movement  be 
adequately  described.  If  this  is  done  successfully,  if 
the  life  of  the  subject-matter  is  ideally  reflected  as  in  a 


XXX  Author's  Prefaces. 

mirror,  then  it  may  appear  as   if  we  liad  before  us  a 
mere  a  priori  construction. 

My  dialectic  method  is  not  only  different  from  the 
Hegeliara,  but  is  its  direct  opposite.  To  Hegel,  the 
life-process  of  the  human  brain,  Le,^  the  process  of 
thinking,  which,  under  the  name  of  *' the  Idea,"  he 
even  transforms  into  an  independent  subject,  is  the 
demiurgos  of  the  real  world,  and  the  real  world  is  only 
the  external,  phenomenal  form  of  "  the  Idea."  With 
me,  on  the  contrary,  the  ideal  is  nothing  else  than  the 
material  world  reflected  by  the  human  mind,  and  trans- 
lated into  forms  of  thought. 

The  mystifying  side  of  Hegelian  dialectic  I  criticised 
nearly  thirty  years  ago,  at  a  time  when  it  was  still  the 
fashion.  But  just  as  I  was  working  at  the  first  volume 
of  "  Das  Kapital,"  it  was  the  good  pleasure  of  the 
peevish,  arrogant,  mediocre  ETnyoi/ot  who  now  talk  large 
in  cultured  Germany,  to  treat  Hegel  in  same  way  as 
the  brave  Moses  Mendelssohn  in  Lessing's  time  treated 
Spinoza,  i.e.^  as  a  "dead  dog."  I  therefore  openly 
avowed  myself  the  pupil  of  that  mighty  thinker,  and 
even  here  and  there,  in  the  chapter  on  the  theory  of  value, 
coquetted  with  the  modes  of  expression  peculiar  to  him. 
The  mystification  which  dialectic  suffers  in  Hegel's  hands, 
by  no  means  prevents  him  from  being  the  first  to  present 
its  general  form  of  working  in  a  comprehensive  and  con- 
scious manner.  With  him  it  is  standing  on  its  head.  It 
must  be  turned  right  side  up  again,  if  you  would  dis- 
cover the  rational  kernel  within  the  mystical  shell. 

In  its  mystified  form,  dialectic  became  the  fashion  in 
Germany,  because  it  seemed  to  transfigure  and  to  glorify 
the  existing  state  of  things.  In  its  rational  form  it  is  a 
scandal  and  abomination  to  bourgeoisdom  and  its  doc- 
trinaire professors,  because  it  includes  in  its  comprehen- 


Autkor^s  Prefaces,  xxxi 

sion  and  affirmative  recognition  of  the  existing  state  of 
things,  at  the  same  time  also,  the  recognition  of  the 
negation  of  that  state,  of  its  inevitable  breaking  up  ; 
because  it  regards  every  historically  developed  social  form 
as  in  fluid  movement,  and  therefore  takes  into  account 
its  transient  nature  not  less  than  its  momentary  exist- 
ence ;  because  it  lets  nothing  impose  upon  it,  and  is  in 
its  essence  critical  and  revolutionary. 

The  contradictions  inherent  in  the  movement  of 
capitalist  society  impress  themselves  upon  the  practical 
bourgeois  most  strikingly  in  the  changes  of  the  periodic 
cycle,  through  which  modern  industry  runs,  and  whose 
crowning  point  is  the  universal  crisis.  That  crisis  is  once 
again  approaching,  although  as  yet  but  in  its  preliminary 
stage ;  and  by  the  universality  of  its  theatre  and  the 
intensity  of  its  action  it  will  drum  dialectics  even  into 
the  heads  of  the  mushroom-upstarts  of  the  new,  holy 
Prusso- German  empire. 

KARL  MARX. 


London,  January  24,  1873. 


BOOK  I. 

CAPITALIST  PRODUCTION. 


PART  I. 
COMMODITIES    AND    MONEY, 


CHAPTER  I. 

COMMODITIES. 

SECTION  1. — THE  TWO  FACTORS  OF  A  COMMODITY  :  USE- VALUE  AND  VALUE 
(the  substance  of  value  and  THE  MAGNITUDE  OF  VALUE). 

THE  wealth  of  those  societies  in  which  the  capitalist  mode 
of  production  prevails,  presents  itself  as  "an  immense 
accumulation  of  commodities,"^  its  unit  being  a  single  com- 
modity. Our  investigation  must  therefore  begin  with  the 
analysis  of  a  commodity. 

A  commodity  is,  in  the  first  place,  an  object  outside  us,  a 
thing  that  by  its  properties  satisfies  human  wants  of  some  sort 
or  another.  The  nature  of  such  wants,  whether,  for  instance, 
they  spring  from  the  stomach  or  from  fancy,  makes  no  dififer- 

1  Karl  Marx  **  Zur  Kritik  der  Politischen  Oekonomie."     Berlin,  1859,  p.  4. 

A 


2  Capitalist  Production, 

ence.^  Neither  are  we  here  concerned  to  know  how  the  object 
satisfies  these  wants,  whether  directly  as  means  of  subsistence, 
or  indirectly  as  means  of  production. 

Every  useful  thing,  as  iron,  paper,  fee,  may  be  looked  at 
from  the  two  points  of  view  of  quality  and  quantity.  It  is 
an  assemblage  of  many  properties,  and  may  therefore  be  of 
use  in  various  ways.  To  discover  the  various  uses  of  things  is 
the  work  of  history,^  So  also  is  the  establishment  of  socially- 
recognised  standards  of  measure  for  the  quantities  of  these 
useful  objects.  The  diversity  of  these  measures  has  its  origin 
partly  in  the  diverse  nature  of  the  objects  to  be  measured, 
partly  in  convention. 

The  utility  of  a  thing  makes  it  a  use-value.^  But  this 
utility  is  not  a  thing  of  air.  Being  limited  by  the  physical 
properties  of  the  commodity,  it  has  no  existence  apart  from] 
that  commodity.  A  commodity,  such  as  iron,  corn,  or  a 
diamond,  is  therefore,  so  far  as  it  is  a  material  thing,  a  use- 
value,  something  useful.  This  property  of  a  commodity  is 
independent  of  the  amount  of  labour  required  to  appropriate 
its  useful  qualities.  When  treating  of  use-value,  we  always 
assume  to  be  dealing  with  definite  quantities,  such  as  dozens 
of  watches,  yards  of  linen,  or  tons  of  iron.  The  use-values  of 
commodities  furnish  the  material  for  a  special  study,  that 
of  the  commercial  knowledge  of  commodities.^  Use-values 
become  a  reality  only  by  use  or  consumption  :  they  also  con- 

1  "  Desire  implies  want ;  it  is  the  appetite  of  the  mind,  and  as  natural  as  hunger  to 
the  body.  .  .  .  The  greatest  number  (of  things)  have  their  value  from  supplying 
the  wants  of  the  mind."  Nicolas  Barbon  :  "A  Discourse  on  coining  the  new  money 
lighter,  in  answer  to  Mr.  Locke's  Considerations,"  &c.     London,  1696.     p.  2,  3. 

2  *'  Things  have  an  intrinsick  vertue  "  (this  is  Barbon 's  special  term  for  value  in  use) 
**  which  in  all  places  have  the  same  vertue  ;  as  the  loadstone  to  attract  iron  "  (I.e., 
p.  6).  The  property  which  the  magnet  possesses  of  attracting  iron,  became  of  use 
only  after  by  means  of  that  property  the  polarity  of  the  magnet  had  been  discovered. 

3  "  The  natural  worth  of  anything  consists  in  its  fitness  to  supply  the  necessities, 
or  serve  the  conveniencies  of  human  life."  (John  Locke,  "Some  considerations  on 
the  consequences  of  the  lowering  of  interest,  1691,"  in  Works  Edit.  Lond.,  1777, 
Vol.  II.,  p.  28.)  In  English  writers  of  the  17th  century  we  frequently  find  "worth" 
in  the  sense  of  value  in  use,  and  "value  "  in  the  sense  of  exchange  value.  This  is 
quite  in  accordance  with  the  spirit  of  a  language  that  likes  to  use  a  Teutonic  word 
for  the  actual  thing,  and  a  Romance  word  for  its  reflexion. 

■*  In  bourgeois  societies  the  economical  fictio  juris  prevails  that  every  one,  as  a 
buyer,  possesses  an  encyclopaedic  knowledge  of  commodities. 


Commodities,  3 

stitute  the  substance  of  all  wealth,  whatever  may  he  the  social 
form  of  that  wealth.  In  the  form  of  society  we  are  about  to 
consider,  they  are,  in  addition,  the  material  depositories  of 
exchange  value. 

Exchange  value,  at  first  sight,  presents  itself  as  a  quantitative 
relation,  as  the  proportion  in  which  values  in  use  of  one  sort 
are  exchanged  for  those  of  another  sort,^  a  relation  constantly 
changing  with  time  and  place.  Hence  exchange  value  appears 
to  be  something  accidental  and  purely  relative,  and  conse- 
quently an  intrinsic  value,  ^.e.,  an  exchange  value  that  is 
inseparably  connected  with,  inherent  in  commodities,  seems  a 
contradiction  in  terms.^  Let  us  consider  the  matter  a  little 
more  closely. 

A  given  commodity,  e.g.^  a  quarter  of  wheat  is  exchanged 
for  X  blacking,  y  silk,  or  z  gold,  &c. — in  short,  for  other  com- 
modities in  the,  most  different  proportions.  Instead  of  one 
exchange  value,  the  wheat  has,  therefore,  a  great  many.  But 
since  x  blacking,  y  silk,  or  z  gold,  &c.,  each  represent  the 
exchange  value  of  one  quarter  of  wheat,  x  blacking,  y  silk, 
z  gold,  &c.,  must,  as  exchange  values,  be  replaceable  by  each 
other,  or  equal  to  each  other.  Therefore,  first :  the  valid 
exchange  values  of  a  given  commodity  express  something 
equal ;  secondly,  exchange  value,  generally,  is  only  the  mode 
of  expression,  the  phenomenal  form,  of  something  contained 
in  ib,  yet  distinguishable  from  it. 

Let  us  take  two  commodities,  e.g.,  corn  and  iron.  The  pro- 
portions in  which  they  are  exchangeable,  whatever  those  pro- 
portions may  be,  can  always  be  represented  by  an  equation  in 
which  a  given  quantity  of  corn  is  equated  to  some  quantity  of 
iron :  e.g.,  1  quarter  corn=x  cwt.  iron.  What  does  this  equa- 
tion tell  us  ?  It  tells  us  that  in  two  difierent  things — in  1 
quarter  of  corn  and  x  cwt.  of  iron,  there  exists  in  equal  quan- 
tities something  common  to  both.     The  two  things  must  there- 

1  "  La  valeur  consiste  dans  le  rapport  d'echange  qui  se  trouve  entre  telle  chose  et 
telle  autre,  entre  telle  mesure  d'une  production,  et  telle  mesure  d'une  autre. "  (Le 
Trosne  :  De  1'  Int^r^t  Social.     Physiocrates,  Ed.  Daire.     Paris,  1845.     P.  889.) 

2  "Nothing  can  have  an  intrinsick  value."  (N.  Barbon,  l.c.,  p.  6) ;  or  as  Butler 
says — 

"  The  value  of  a  thing 
Is  just  as  much  as  it  will  bring." 


4  Capitalist  Production. 

fore  be  equal  to  a  third,  which  in  itself  is  neither  the  one  nor 
the  other.  Each  of  them,  so  far  as  it  is  exchange  value,  must 
therefore  be  reducible  to  this  third. 

A  simple  geometrical  illustration  will  make  this  clear.  In 
order  to  ca,lculate  and  compare  the  areas  of  rectilinear  figures, 
we  decompose  them  into  triangles.  But  the  area  of  the  tri- 
angle itself  is  expressed  by  something  totally  different  from  its 
visible  figure,  namely,  by  half  the  product  of  the  base  into 
the  altitude.  In  the  same  way  the  exchange  values  of  com- 
modities must  be  capable  of  being  expressed  in  terms  of  some- 
thing common  to  them  all,  of  which  thing  they  represent  a 
greater  or  less  quantity. 

This  common  "  something  "  cannot  be  either  a  geometrical, 
a  chemical,  or  any  other  natural  property  of  commodities. 
Such  properties  claim  our  attention  only  in  so  far  as  they 
affect  the  utility  of  those  commodities,  make  them  use-values. 
But  the  exchange  of  commodities  is  evidently  an  act  character- 
ised by  a  total  abstrstction  from  use- value.  Then  one  use- 
value  is  just  as  good  as  another,  provided  only  it  be  present  in 
sufficient  quantity.  Or,  as  old  Barbon  says,  "one  sort  of 
wares  are  as  good  as  another,  if  the  values  be  equal.  There  is 
no  difference  or  distinction  in  things  of  equal  value  .... 
An  hundred  pounds'  worth  of  lead  or  iron,  is  of  as  great  value 
as  one  hundred  pounds'  worth  of  silver  or  gold."^  As  use-values, 
commodities  are,  above  all,  of  different  qualities,  but  as  ex- 
change values  they  are  merely  different  quantities,  and  conse- 
quently do  not  contain  an  atom  of  use-value. 

If  then  we  leave  out  of  consideration  the  use-value  of  com- 
modities, they  have  only  one  common  property  left,  that  of 
being  products  of  labour.  But  even  the  product  of  labour 
itself  has  undergone  a  change  in  our  hands.  If  we  make 
abstraction  from  its  use-value,  we  make  abstraction  at  the 
same  time  from  the  material  elements  and  shapes  that  make 
the  product  a  use- value ;  we  see  in  it  no  longer  a  table,  a  house, 
yarn,  or  any  other  useful  thing.  Its  existence  as  a  material 
thing  is  put  out  of  sight.  Neither  can  it  any  longer  be  re- 
garded as  the  product  of  the  labour  of  the  joiner,  the  mason, 

1 N.  Barbon,  1.  c.  p.  53  and  7. 


Commodities,  5 

the  spinner,  or  of  any  other  definite  kind  of  productive 
labour.  Along  with  the  useful  qualities  of  the  products  them- 
selves, we  put  out  of  sight  both  the  useful  character  of  the 
various  kinds  of  labour  embodied  in  them,  and  the  concrete 
forms  of  that  labour ;  there  is  nothing  left  but  what  is  common 
to  them  all;  all  are  reduced  to  one  and  the  same  sort  of 
labour,  human  labour  in  the  abstract. 

Let  us  now  consider  the  residue  of  each  of  these  products  ; 
it  consists  of  the  same  unsubstantijj[_reality  in  each,  a  mere 
congelation  of^miogeneous  human  labour,  of  labour-power  ex- 
pended without  regard  to  the  mode  of  its  expenditure.  AIL 
that  these  things  now  tell  us  is,  that  human  labour-power  has 
been  expended  in  their  production,  that  human  labour  is  em- 
bodied in  them.  When  looked  at  as  crystals  of  this  social 
substance,  common  to  them  all,  they  are — Values. 

We  have  seen  that  when  commodities  are  exchanged,  their 
exchange  value  manifests  itself  as  something  totally  independ- 
l  ent  of  their  use-value.     But  if  we  abstract  from  their  use- value,  \ 
<;  there  remains  their  Value  as  defined  above.      Therefore,  the  ^ 
common  substance  that  manifests  itself  in  the  exchange  value 
of  commodities,  whenever  they  are  exchanged,  is  their  value. 
The  progress  of  our  investigation  will  show  that  exchange 
value  is  the  only  form  in  which  the  value  of  commodities  can 
manifest  itself  or  be  expressed.     For  the  present,  however,  we 
have  to  consider  the  nature  of  value  independently  of  this,  its 
form. 
^       A  use-value,  or  useful  article,  therefore,  has  value  only  because  S 
/  human  labour  in  the  abstract  has  been  embodied  or  material-  Z 
^  ised  in  it.     How,  then,  is  the  magnitude  of  this  value  to  be     - 
measured  ?      Plainly,  by  the  quantity  of  the  value-creating 
substance,  the  labour,  contained  in  the  article.     The  quantity 
of  labour,  however,  is  measured  by  its  duration,  and  labour- 
time  in  its  turn  finds  its  standard  in  weeks,  days,  and  hours. 

Some  people  might  think  that  if  the  value  of  a  commodity 
is  determined  by  the  quantity  of  labour  spent  on  it,  the  more 
idle  and  unskilful  the  labourer,  the  more  valuable  would  his 
commodity  be,  because  more  time  would  be  required  in  its 
production.   (The  labour,  however,  that  forms  the  substance  of 


r 


L 


6  Capitalist  Production. 

value,  is  homogeneous  human  labour,  expenditure  of  one  uniform 
labour-power.  /The  total  labour-power  of  society,  which  is 
embodied  in  the  sum  total  of  the  values  of  all  commodities  pro- 
duced by  that  society,  counts  here  as  one  homogeneous  mass  of 
human  labour-power,  composed  though  it  be  of  innumerable 
individual  units.  Each  of  these  units  is  the  same  as  any  other, 
so  far  as  it  has  the  character  of  the  average  labour-power  of 
society,  and  takes  effect  as  such;  that  is,  so  far  as  it  requires  for 
producing  a  commodity,  no  more  time  than  is  needed  on  an 
average,  no  more  than  is  socially  necessary.  The  labour-time 
socially  necessary  is  that  required  to  produce  an  article  under 
the  normal  conditions  of  production,  and  with  the  average 
degree  of  skill  and  intensity  prevalent  at  the  time.  The  intro- 
duction of  power  looms  into  England  probably  reduced  by  one 
half  the  labour  required  to  weave  a  given  quantity  of  yarn  into 
cloth.  The  hand-loom  weavers,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  continued 
to  require  the  same  time  as  before ;  but  for  all  that,  the  pro- 
duct of  one  hour  of  their  labour  represented  after  the  change 
only  half  an  hour's  social  labour,  and  consequently  fell  to  one- 
half  its  former  value. 

We  see  then  that  that  which  determines  the  magnitude  of 
the  value  of  any  article  is  the  amount  of  labour  socially  neces- 
sary, or  the  labour-time  socially  necessary  for  its  production.* 
Each  individual  commodity,  in  this  connexion,  is  to  be  con- 
sidered as  an  average  sample  of  its  class.^  Commodities,  there-  / 
fore,  in  which  equal  quantities  of  labour  are  embodied,  or 
which  can  be  produced  in  the  same  time,  have  the  same  value. 
The  value  of  one  commodity  is  to  the  value  of  any  other,  as  the 
labour-time  necessary  for  the  production  of  the  one  is  to  that 
n  necessary  for  the  production  of  ihe  other.  "  As  values,  all  com- 
modities are  only  definite  masses  of  congealed  labour-time."^     - 


/ 


1  "The  value  of  them  (the  necessaries  of  life),  when  they  are  exchanged  the  one  for 
another,  is  regulated  by  the  quantity  of  labour  necessarily  required,  and  commonly 
taken  in  producing  them."  (Some  Thoughts  on  the  Interest  of  Money  in  general,  and 
particularly  in  the  Publick  Funds,  &c.  Lond.,  p.  36.)  This  remarkable  anonymous 
work,  written  in  the  last  century,  bears  no  date.  It  is  clear,  however,  from  internal 
evidence,  that  it  appeared  in  the  reign  of  George  II.  about  1739  or  1740. 

^  '*  Toutes  les  productions  d'un  meme  genre  ne  forraent  proprement  qu'une  masse, 
dont  le  prix  se  determine  en  general  et  sans  egard  aux  circonstances  particulieres." 
(Le  Trosne,  1.  c.  p.  893.  3  K.  Marx.   1.  c.  p.  6. 


Commodities.  7 

The  value  of  a  commodity  would  therefore  remain  constant, 
if  the  labour-time  required  for  its  production  also  remained 
constant.  But  the  latter  changes  with  every  variation  in  the 
productiveness  of  labour.  This  productiveness  is  determined 
by  various  circumstances,  amongst  others,  by  the  average 
amount  of  skill  of  the  workmen,  the  state  of  science,  and  the 
degree  of  its  practical  application,  the  social  organisation  of 
production,  the  extent  and  capabilities  of  the  means  of  pro- 
duction, and  by  physical  conditions.  For  example,  the 
same  amount  of  labour  in  favourable  seasons  is  embodied 
in  8  bushels  of  corn,  and  in  unfavourable,  only  in  four. 
The  same  labour  extracts  from  rich  mines  more  metal  than 
from  poor  mines.  Diamonds  are  of  very  rare  occurrence  on 
the  earth's  surface,  and  hence  their  discovery  costs,  on  an  aver- 
age, a  great  deal  of  labour-time.  Consequently  much  labour 
is  represented  in  a  small  compass.  Jacob  doubts  whether  gold 
has  ever  been  paid  for  at  its  full  value.  This  applies  still 
more  to  diamonds.  According  to  Eschwege,  the  total  produce 
of  the  Brazilian  diamond  mines  for  the  eighty  years,  ending 
in  1823,  had  not  realised  the  price  of  one-and-a-half  years* 
average  produce  of  the  sugar  and  coffee  plantations  of  the 
same  country,  although  the  diamonds  cost  much  more  labour, 
and  therefore  represented  more  value.  With  richer  mines,  the 
same  quantity  of  labour  would  embody  itself  in  more  diamonds, 
and  their  value  would  fall.  If  we  could  succeed  at  a  small 
expenditure  of  labour,  in  converting  carbon  into  diamonds, 
their  value  might  fall  below  that  of  *bricks.  In  general,  the 
greater  the  productiveness  of  labour,  the  less  is  the  labour-time 
required  for  the  production  of  an  article,  the  less  is  the  amount 
of  labour  crystallised  in  that  article,  and  the  less  is  its  value ; 
and  vice  versd,  the  less  the  productiveness  of  labour,  the  greater 
is  the  labour-time  required  for  the  production  of  an  article, 
and  the  greater  is  its  value.  The  value  of  a  commodity,  there- 
fore, varies  directly  as  the  quantity,  and  inversely  as  the 
productiveness,  of  the  labour  incorporated  in  it. 

A  thing  can  be  a  use-value,  without  having  value.  This  is 
the  case  whenever  its  utility  to  man  is  not  due  to  labour. 
Such  are  air,  virgin  soil,  natural  meadows,  &;c.     A  thing  can 


/ 


i 


8  Capitalist  Production. 

be  useful,  and  the  product  of  human  labour,  without  being  a 
commodity.  Whoever  directly  satisfies  his  wants  with  the 
produce  of  his  own  labour,  creates,  indeed,  use-values,  but  not 
commodities.  In  order  to  produce  the  latter,  he  must  not  only 
produce  use-values,  but  use-values  for  others,  social  use-values. 
Lastly,  nothing  can  have  value,  without  being  an  object  of 
utility.  If  the  thing  is  useless,  so  is  the  labour  contained  in 
it ;  the  labour  does  not  count  as  labour,  and  therefore  creates 
no  value. 


SECTION     2.— THE     TWOFOLD     CHARACTER     OF     THE    LABOUR     EMBODIED    IN 

COMMODITIES. 

At  first  sight  a  commodity  presented  itself  to  us  as  a  complex 
of  two  things — use-value  and  exchange-value.  Later  on,  we 
saw  also  that  labour,  too,  possesses  the  same  two-fold  nature ; 
for,  so  far  as  it  finds  expression  in  value,  it  does  not  possess  the 
same  characteristics  that  belong  to  it  as  a  creator  of  use-values. 
I  was  the  first  to  point  out  and  to  examine  critically  this  two- 
fold nature  of  the  labour  contained  in  commodities.  As  this 
point  is  the  pivot  on  which  a  clear  comprehension  of  political 
economy  turns,  we  must  go  more  into  detail. 

Let  us  take  two  commodities  such  as  a  coat  and  10  yards  of 
linen,  and  let  the  former  be  double  the  value  of  the  latter,  so 
that,  if  10  yards  of  linen=W,  the  coat=2W. 

The  coat  is  a  use-value  that  satisfies  a  particular  want.  Its 
existence  is  the  result  of  a  special  sort  of  productive  activity, 
the  nature  of  which  is  determined  by  its  aim,  mode  of  opera- 
tion, subject,  means,  and  result.  The  labour,  whose  utility  is 
thus  represented  by  the  value  in  use  of  its  product,  or  which 
manifests  itself  by  making  its  product  a  use-value,  we  call 
useful  labour.  In  this  connexion  we  consider  only  its  useful 
efiect. 

As  the  coat  and  the  linen  are  two  qualitatively  difierent  use- 
values,  so  also  are  the  two  forms  of  labour  that  produce  them, 
tailoring  and  weaving.  Were  these  two  objects  not  quali- 
tatively difierent,  not  produced  respectively  by  labour  of 
different  quality,  they  could  not  stand  to  each  other  in  the 


Commodities,  9 

relation  of  commodities.     Coats  are  not  exchanged  for  coats, 
one  use- value  is  not  exchanged  for  another  of  the  same  kind. 

To  all  the  different  varieties  of  values  in  use  there  correspond  as 
many  different  kinds  of  useful  labour,  classified  according  to  the 
order,  genus,  species,  and  variety  to  which  they  belong  in  the 
social  division  of  labour.  This  division  of  labour  is  a  necessary 
condition  for  the  production  of  commodities,  but  it  does  not 
follow,  conversely,  that  the  production  of  commodities  is  a 
necessary  condition  for  the  division  of  labour.  In  the  primitive 
Indian  community  there  is  social  division  of  labour,  without 
production  of  commodities.  Or,  to  take  an  example  nearer 
home,  in  every  factory  the  labour  is  divided  according  to  a 
system,  but  this  division  is  not  brought  about  by  the  operatives 
mutually  exchanging  their  individual  products.  Only  such 
products  can  become  commodities  with  regard  to  each  other,  as 
result  from  different  kinds  of  labour,  each  kind  being  carried 
on  independently  and  for  the  account  of  private  individuals. 

To  resume,  then :  In  the  use-value  of  each  commodity  there 
is  contained  useful  labour,  i.e.,  productive  activity  of  a  definite 
kind  and  exercised  with  a  definite  aim.  Use-values  cannot 
confront  each  other  as  commodities,  unless  the  useful  labour/ 
embodied  in  them  is  qualitatively  different  in  each  of  them. 
In  a  community,  the  produce  of  which  in  general  takes  the' 
form  of  commodities,  i.e.,  in  a  community  of  commodity  pro- 
ducers, this  qualitative  difference  between  the  useful  forms  of 
labour  that  are  carried  on  independently  by  individual  pro- 
ducers, each  on  their  own  account,  develops  into  a  complex 
system,  a  social  division  of  labour. 

Anyhow,  whether  the  coat  be  worn  by  the  tailor  or  by  his 
customer,  in  either  case  it  operates  as  a  use- value.  Nor  is  the 
relation  between  the  coat  and  the  labour  that  produced  it 
altered  by  the  circumstance  that  tailoring  may  have  become  a 
special  trade,  an  independent  branch  of  the  social  division  of 
labour.  Wherever  the  want  of  clothing  forced  them  to  it,  the 
human  race  made  clothes  for  thousands  of  years,  without  a 
single  man  becoming  a  tailor.  But  coats  and  linen,  like  every 
other  element  of  material  wealth  that  is  not  the  spontaneous 
produce  of  nature,  must  invariably  owe  their  existence  to  a 


lo  Capitalist  Prodtiction. 

special  productive  activity,  exercised  with  a  definite  aim,  an 
activity  that  appropriates  particular  nature-given  materials  to 
particular  human  wants.  So  far  therefore  as  labour  is  a 
creator  of  use-value,  is  useful  labour,  it  is  a  necessary  con- 
dition, independent  of  all  forms  of  society,  for  the  existence  of 
the  human  race;  it  is  an  eternal  nature-imposed  necessity, 
without  which  there  can  be  no  material  exchanges  between 
man  and  Nature,  and  therefore  no  life. 

The  use-values,  coat,  linen,  &;c.,  i.e.,  the  bodies  of  commodi- 
ties, are  combinations  of  two  elements — matter  and  labour. 
If  we  take  away  the  useful  labour  expended  upon  them,  a 
material  substratum  is  always  left,  which  is  furnished  by 
Nature  without  the  help  of  man.  The  latter  can  work  only 
as  Nature  does,  that  is  by  changing  the  form  of  matter.^  Nay 
more,  in  this  work  of  changing  the  form  he  is  constantly  helped 
by  natural  forces.  We  see,  then,  that  labour  is  not  the  only 
source  of  material  wealth,  of  use- values  produced  by  labour. 
As  William  Petty  puts  it,  labour  is  its  father  and  the  earth  its 
mother. 

Let  us  now  pass  from  the  commodity  considered  as  a  use- 
value  to  the  value  of  commodities. 

By  our  assumption,  the  coat  is  worth  twice  as  much  as  the 
linen.  But  this  is  a  mere  quantitative  difference,  which  for  the 
present  does  not  concern  us.  We  bear  in  mind,  however,  that 
if  the  value  of  the  coat  is  double  that  of  10  yds.  of  linen,  20 
yds.  of  linen  must  have  the  same  value  as  one  coat.  So  far 
as  they  are  values,  the  coat  and  the  linen  are  things  of  a  like 
substance,  objective  expressions  of  essentially  identical  labour. 
But  tailoring  and  weaving  are,  qualitatively,  different  kinds  of 

^  Tutti  i  fenomeni  dell'  universe,  sieno  essi  prodotti  della  mano  dell'  uomo,  ovvero 
delle  universali  leggi  della  fisica,  non  ci  danno  idea  di  attuale  creazione,  ma  unica- 
mente  di  una  modificazione  della  materia.  Accostare  e  separare  sono  gli  unici  ele- 
menti  che  I'ingegno  umano  ritrova  analizzando  I'idea  della  riproduzione :  e  tanto  d  ri- 
produzione  di  valore  (value  in  use,  although  Verri  in  this  passage  of  his  controversy 
with  the  Physiocrats  is  not  himself  quite  certain  of  the  kind  of  value  he  is  speaking 
of)  e  di  ricchezze  se  la  terra  I'aria  e  I'acqua  ne'  campi  si  trasmutino  in  grano,  come  se 
coUa  mano  dell'  uomo  il  glutine  di  un  insctto  si  trasmuti  in  velluto  owero  alcuni  pez- 
zetti  di  metallo  si  organizzino  a  formare  una  ripetizione." — Pietro  Verri.  "  Medita- 
zioni  suUa  Economia  Politica  "  [first  printed  in  1773]  in  Custodi's  edition  of  the 
Italian  Economists,  Parte  Moderna,  t.  xv.  p.  22. 


Commodities.  1 1 

labour.  There  are,  however,  states  of  society  in  which  one  and 
the  same  man  does  tailoring  and  weaving  alternately,  in  which 
case  these  two  forms  of  labour  are  mere  modifications  of  the 
labour  of  the  same  individual,  and  not  special  and  fixed  func- 
tions of  different  persons ;  just  as  the  coat  which  our  tailor 
makes  one  day,  and  the  trousers  which  he  makes  another  day, 
imply  only  a  variation  in  the  labour  of  one  and  the  same  indi- 
vidual. Moreover,  we  see  at  a  glance  that,  in  our  capitalist 
society,  a  given  portion  of  human  labour  is,  in  accordance  with 
the  varying  demand,  at  one  time  supplied  in  the  form  of  tailor- 
ing, at  another  in  the  form  of  weaving.  This  change  may 
possibly  not  take  place  without  friction,  but  take  place  it  must. 
Productive  activity,  if  we  leave  out  of  sight  its  special  form, 
viz.,  the  useful  character  of  the  labour,  is  nothing  but  the  ex- 
penditure of  human  labour-power.  Tailoring  and  weaving, 
though  qualitatively  different  productive  activities,  are  each  a 
productive  expenditure  of  human  brains,  nerves,  and  muscles, 
and  in  this  sense  are  human  labour.  They  are  but  two 
different  modes  of  expending  human  labour-power.  Of  course, 
this  labour-power,  which  remains  the  same  under  all  its  modi- 
fications, must  have  attained  a  certain  pitch  of  development 
before  it  can  be  expended  in  a  multiplicity  of  modes.  But  the 
value  of  a  commodity  represents  human  labour  in  the  abstract, 
the  expenditure  of  human  labour  in  general.  And  just  as  in 
society,  a  general  or  a  banker  plays  a  great  part,  but  mere 
man,  on  the  other  hand,  a  very  shabby  part,^  so  here  with 
mere  human  labour.  It  is  the  expenditure  of  simple  labour- 
power,  i.e.,  of  the  labour-power  which,  on  an  average,  apart 
from  any  special  development,  exists  in  the  organism  of  every 
ordinary  individual.  Simple  average  labour,  it  is  true,  varies 
in  character  in  diflferent  countries  and  at  different  times,  but 
in  a  particular  society  it  is  given.  Skilled  labour  counts  only 
as  simple  labour  intensified,  or  rather,  as  multiplied  simple 
labour,  a  given  quantity  of  skilled  being  considered  equal  to  a 
greater  quantity  of  simple  labour.  Experience  shows  that  this 
reduction  is  constantly  being  made.  A  commodity  may  be  the 
product  of  the  most  skilled  labour,  but  its  value,  by  equating 

1  Oomp.  Hegel,  Philosophie  des  Rechts.    Berlin,  1840.    P.  250  §  190. 


12  Capitalist  Production. 

it  to  the  product  of  simple  unskilled  labour,  represents  a 
definite  quantity  of  the  latter  labour  alone.^  The  different 
proportions  in  which  different  sorts  of  labour  are  reduced  to 
unskilled  labour  as  their  standard,  are  established  by  a  social 
process  that  goes  on  behind  the  backs  of  the  producers,  and, 
consequently,  appear  to  be  fixed  by  custom.  For  simplicity's 
sake  we  shall  henceforth  account  every  kind  of  labour  to  be 
unskilled,  simple  labour;  by  this  we  do  no  more  than  save 
ourselves  the  trouble  of  making  the  reduction. 

Just  as,  therefore,  in  viewing  the  coat  and  linen  as  values, 
we  abstract  from  their  difierent  use-values,  so  it  is  with  the 
labour  represented  hy  those  values  :  we  disregard  the  difference 
between  its  useful  forms,  weaving  and  tailoring.  As  the  use- 
values,  coat  and  linen,  are  combinations  of  special  productive 
activities  with  cloth  and  yarn,  while  the  values,  coat  and  linen, 
are,  on  the  other  hand,  mere  homogeneous  congelations  of 
undifferentiated  labour,  so  the  labour  embodied  in  these  latter 
values  does  not  count  by  virtue  of  its  productive  relation  to 
cloth  and  yarn,  but  only  as  being  expenditure  of  human 
labour-power.  Tailoring  and  weaving  are  necessary  factors  in 
the  creation  of  the  use-values,  coat  and  linen,  precisely  because 
these  two  kinds  of  labour  are  of  difierent  qualities ;  but  only 
in  so  far  as  abstraction  is  made  from  their  special  qualities, 
only  in  so  far  as  both  possess  the  same  quality  of  being  human 
labour,  do  tailoring  and  weaving  form  the  substance  of  the 
values  of  the  same  articles. 

Coats  and  linen,  however,  are  not  merely  values,  but  values 
of  definite  magnitude,  and  according  to  our  assumption,  the 
coat  is  worth  twice  as  much  as  the  ten  yards  of  linen.  Whence 
this  difference  in  their  values  ?  It  is  owing  to  the  fact  that 
the  linen  contains  only  half  as  much  labour  as  the  coat, 
and  consequently  that  in  the  production  of  the  latter,  labour- 
power  must  have  been  expended  during  twice  the  time 
necessary  for  the  production  of  the  former. 

While,  therefore,  with  reference  to  use-value,  the  labour  con- 

1  The  reader,  must  note  that  we  are  not  speaking  here  of  the  wages  or  value  that 
the  labourer  gets  for  a  given  labour  time,  but  of  the  value  of  the  commodity  in  which 
that  labour  time  is  materialised.  Wages  is  a  category  that,  as  yet,  has  no  existence 
at  the  present  stage  of  our  investigation. 


Commodities,  1 3 

tained  in  a  commodity  counts  only  qualitatively,  with  refer- 
ence to  value  it  counts  only  quantitatively,  and  must  first  be 
reduced  to  human  labour  pure  and  simple.  In  the  former 
case,  it  is  a  question  of  How  and  What,  in  the  latter  of  How 
much  ?  How  long  a  time  ?  Since  the  magnitude  of  the  value  of 
a  commodity  represents  only  the  quantity  of  labour  embodied 
in  it,  it  follows  that  all  commodities,  when  taken  in  certain 
proportions,  must  be  equal  in  value. 

H  the  productive  power  of  all  the  different  sorts  of  useful 
labour  required  for  the  production  of  a  coat  remains  unchanged, 
the  sum  of  the  values  of  the  coats  produced  increases  with 
their  number.  If  one  coat  represents  x  days'  labour,  two 
coats  represent  2x  days'  labour,  and  so  on.  But  assume  that 
the  duration  of  the  labour  necessary  for  the  production  of  a 
coat  becomes  doubled  or  halved.  In  the  first  case,  one  coat  is 
worth  as  much  as  two  coats  were  before  ;  in  the  second  case, 
two  coats  are  only  worth  as  much  as  one  was  before,  although 
in  both  cases  one  coat  renders  the  same  service  as  before,  and 
the  useful  labour  embodied  in  it  remains  of  the  same  quality. 
But  the  quantity  of  labour  spent  on  its  production  has  altered. 

An  increase  in  the  quantity  of  use-values  is  an  increase  of 
material  wealth.  With  two  coats  two  men  can  be  clothed, 
with  one  coat  only  one  man.  Nevertheless,  an  increased 
quantity  of  material  wealth  may  correspond  to  a  simultaneous 
fall  in  the  magnitude  of  its  value.  This  antagonistic  move- 
ment has  its  origin  in  the  two-fold  character  of  labour. 
Productive  power  has  reference,  of  course,  only  to  labour  of 
some  useful  concrete  form ;  the  efficacy  of  any  special  produc- 
tive activity  during  a  given  time  being  dependent  on  its 
productiveness.  Useful  labour  becomes,  therefore,  a  more  or 
less  abundant  source  of  products,  in  proportion  to  the  rise  or 
fall  of  its  productiveness.  On  the  other  hand,  no  change  in  this 
productiveness  affects  the  labour  represented  by  value.  Since 
productive  power  is  an  attribute  of  the  concrete  useful  forms 
of  labour,  of  course  it  can  no  longer  have  any  bearing  on  that 
labour,  so  soon  as  we  make  abstraction  from  those  concrete 
useful  forms.  However  then  productive  power  may  vary,  the 
same  labour,  exercised  during  equal  periods  of  time,  always 


^ 


( 


14  Capitalist  Production 

yields  equal  amounts  of  value.  But  it  will  yield,  during  equal 
periods  of  time,  different  quantities  of  values  in  use ;  more,  if 
the  productive  power  rise,  fewer,  if  it  fall.  The  same  change 
in  productive  power,  which  increases  the  fruitfulness  of  labour, 
and,  in  consequence,  the  quantity  of  use-values  produced  by 
that  labour,  will  diminish  the  total  value  of  this  increased 
quantity  of  use-values,  provided  such  change  shorten  the  total 
labour-time  necessary  for  their  production ;  and  vice  versa. 

On  the  one  hand  all  labour  is,  speaking  physiologically,  an 
expenditure  of  human  labour-power,  and  in  its  character  of 
identical  abstract  human  labour,  it  creates  and  forms  the  value 
of  commodities.  On  the  other  hand,  all  labour  is  the  expendi- 
ture of  human  labour-power  in  a  special  form  and  with  a 
definite  aim,  and  in  this,  its  character  of  concrete  useful  labour, 
it  produces  use-values.^ 

SECTION  3. — THE  FORM  OP  VALUE  OR  EXCHANGE  VALUE. 

Commodities  come  into  the  world  in  the  shape  of  use- values, 
articles,  or  goods,  such  as  iron,  linen,  corn,  &ic.     This  is  their 

1  In  order  to  prove  that  labour  alone  is  that  all-sufficient  and  real  measure,  by 
which  at  all  times  the  value  of  all  commodities  can  be  estimated  and  compared, 
Adam  Smith  says,  "  Equal  quantities  of  labour  must  at  all  times  and  in  all  places 
have  the  same  value  for  the  labourer.  In  his  normal  state  of  health,  strength,  and 
activity,  and  with  the  average  degree  of  skill  that  he  may  possess,  he  must  always 
give  up  the  same  portion  of  his  rest,  his  freedom,  and  his  happiness."  (Wealth  of 
Nations,  b.  I.  ch.  v.)  On  the  one  hand,  Adam  Smith  here  (but  not  everywhere)  con- 
fuses the  determination  of  value  by  means  of  the  quantity  of  labour  expended  in  the 
production  of  commodities,  with  the  determination  of  the  values  of  commodities  by 
means  of  the  value  of  labour,  and  seeks  in  consequence  to  prove  that  equal  quantities 
of  labour  have  always  the  same  value.  On  the  other  hand,  he  has  a  presentiment, 
that  labour,  so  far  as  it  manifests  itself  in  the  value  of  commodities,  counts  only  as 
expenditure  of  labour  power,  but  he  treats  this  expenditure  as  the  mere  sacrifice  of 
rest,  freedom,  and  happiness,  not  as  at  the  same  time  the  normal  activity  of  living 
beings.  But  then,  he  has  the  modern  wage-labourer  in  his  eye.  Much  more  aptly, 
the  anonymous  predecessor  of  Adam  Smith,  quoted  above  in  Note  i,  p.  6,  says  "one  man 
has  employed  himself  a  week  in  j)roviding  this  necessary  of  life  .  .  .  and  he  that 
gives  him  some  other  in  exchange,  cannot  make  a  better  estimate  of  what  is  a  pro- 
per equivalent,  than  by  computing  what  cost  him  just  as  much  labour  and  time; 
which  in  effect  is  no  more  than  exchanging  one  man's  labour  in  one  thing  for  a  time 
certain,  for  another  man's  labour  in  another  thing  for  the  same  time."  (1.  c.  p.  39.) 
[The  English  language  has  the  advantage  of  possessing  different  words  for  the  two 
aspects  of  labour  here  considered.  The  labour  which  creates  Use-Value,  and  counts 
qualitatively,  is  Work,  as  distinguished  from  Labour  ;  that  which  creates  Value  and 
counts  quantitatively,  is  Labour  as  distinguished  from  Work. — Ed.] 


Commodities,  1 5 

plain,  homely,  bodily  form.  They  are,  however,  commodities, 
only  because  they  are  something  twofold,  both  objects  of  utility, 
and,  at  the  same  time,  depositories  of  value.  They  manifest 
themselves  therefore  as  commodities,  or  have  the  form  of  com- 
modities, only  in  so  far  as  they  have  two  forms,  a  physical 
or  natural  form,  and  a  value  form. 

The  reality  of  the  value  of  commodities  differs  in  this  respect 
from  Dame  Quickly,  that  we  don't  know  "  where  to  have  it." 
The  value  of  commodities  is  the  very  opposite  of  the  coarse  mate- 
riality of  their  substance,  not  an  atom  of  matter  enters  into  its  1 
composition.  Turn  and  examine  a  single  commodity,  by  itself, 
as  we  will,  yet  in  so  far  as  it  remains  an  object  of  value,  it 
seems  impossible  to  grasp  it.  If,  however,  we  bear  in  mind  that 
the  value  of  commodities  has  a  purely  social  realit}^,  and  that 
they  acquire  this  reality  only  in  so  far  as  they  are  expressions 
or  embodiments  of  one  identical  social  substance,  viz.,  human 
labour,  it  follows  as  a  matter  of  course,  that  value  can  only 
manifest  itself  in  the  social  relation  of  commodity  to  com- 
modity. In  fact  we  started  from  exchange  value,  or  the 
exchange  relation  of  commodities,  in  order  to  get  at  the  value 
that  lies  hidden  behind  it.  We  must  now  return  to  this  form 
under  which  value  first  appeared  to  us. 

Every  one  knows,  if  he  knows  nothing  else,  that  commodities 
have  a  value  form  common  to  them  all,  and  presenting  a 
marked  contrast  with  the  varied  bodily  forms  of  their  use- 
values.  I  mean  their  money  form.  Here,  however,  a  task  is  set 
us,  the  performance  of  which  has  never  yet  even  been  attempted 
by  bourgeois  economy,  the  task  of  tracing  the  genesis  of  this 
money  form,  of  developing  the  expression  of  value  implied  in 
the  value  relation  of  commodities,  from  its  simplest,  almost 
imperceptible  outline,  to  the  dazzling  money  form.  By  doing 
this  we  shall,  at  the  same  time,  solve  the  riddle  presented  by 
money. 

The  simplest  value  relation  is  evidently  that  of  one  com- 
modity to  some  one  other  commodity  of  a  different  kind. 
Hence  the  relation  between  the  values  of  two  commodities  sup- 
plies us  with  the  simplest  expression  of  the  value  of  a  single 
commodity. 


1 6  Capitalist  Production, 

A.  Elementary  or  Accidental  Form  of  Value. 

X  commodity  A  =  y  commodity  B,  or 
X  commodity  A  is  worth  y  commodity  B. 

20  yards  of  linen  ==  1  coat,  or 

20  yards  of  linen  are  worth  1  coat. 

1.  The  two  poles  of  the  expression  of  value :  Relative  form  and 
Equivalent  form. 

The  whole  mystery  of  the  form  of  value  lies  hidden  in 
this  elementary  form.  Its  analysis,  therefore,  is  our  real 
difficulty. 

Here  two  different  kinds  of  commodities  (in  our  example 
the  linen  and  the  coat),  evidently  play  two  different  parts. 
The  linen  expresses  its  value  in  the  coat;  the  coat  serves  as  the 
material  in  which  that  value  is  expressed.  The  former  plays 
an  active,  the  latter  a  passive,  part.  The  value  of  the  linen  is 
represented  as  relative  value,  or  appears  in  relative  form. 
Tlie  coat  officiates  as  equivalent,  or  appears  in  equivalent 
form. 

The  relative  form  and  the  equivalent  form  are  two  intimately 
connected,  mutually  dependent  and  inseparable  elements  of  the 
expression  of  value ;  but,  at  the  same  time,  are  mutually 
exclusive,  antagonistic  extremes — i.e.y  poles  of  the  same 
expression.  They  are  allotted  respectively  to  the  two  different 
commodities  brought  into  relation  by  that  expression.  It  is 
not  possible  to  express  the  value  of  linen  in  linen.  20  yards 
of  linen  =  20  yards  of  linen  is  no  expression  of  value.  On  the 
contrary,  such  an  equation  merely  says  that  20  yards  of  linen 
are  nothing  else  than  20  yards  of  linen,  a  definite  quantity  of 
the  use-value  linen.  The  value  of  the  linen  can  therefore  be 
expressed  only  relatively — i.e.,  in  some  other  commodity.  The 
relative  form  of  the  value  of  the  linen  pre-supposes,  therefore, 
the  presence  of  some  other  commodity — here  the  coat — under 
the  form  of  an  equivalent.  On  the  other  hand,  the  commodity 
that  figures  as  the  equivalent  cannot  at  the  same  time  assume 
the  relative  form.  That  second  commodity  is  not  the  one 
whose  value  is  expressed.     Its  function  is  merely  to  serve  as 


Commodities.  1 7 

the  material  in  which  the  value  of  the  first  commodity  is 
expressed. 

No  doubt,  the  expression  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat,  or  20 
yards  of  linen  are  worth  1  coat,  implies  the  opposite  relation :  1 
coat  =  20  yards  of  linen,  or  1  coat  is  worth  20  yards  of  linen. 
But,  in  that  case,  I  must  reverse  the  equation,  in  order  to 
express  the  value  of  the  coat  relatively ;  and,  so  soon  as  I  do 
that,  the  linen  becomes  the  equivalent  instead  of  the  coat. 
A  single  commodity  cannot,  therefore,  simultaneously  assume, 
in  the  same  expression  of  value,  both  forms.  The  very 
polarity  of  these  forms  makes  them  mutually  exclusive. 

Whether,  then,  a  commodity  assumes  the  relative  form,  or 
the  opposite  equivalent  form,  depends  entirely  upon  its  acci- 
dental position  in  the  expression  of  value — that  is,  upon 
whether  it  is  the  commodity  whose  value  is  being  expressed  or 
the  commodity  in  which  value  is  being  expressed. 

2.  The  Relative  form  of  value. 
(a.)  The  nature  and  import  of  this  form. 

In  order  to  discover  Low  the  elementary  expression  of  the 
value  of  a  commodity  lies  hidden  in  the  value  relation  of  two 
commodities,  we  must,  in  the  first  place,  consider  the  latter 
entirely  apart  from  its  quantitative  aspect.  The  usual  mode  of 
procedure  is  generally  the  reverse,  and  in  the  value  relation 
nothing  is  seen  but  the  proportion  between  definite  quantities 
of  two  different  sorts  of  commodities  that  are  considered  equal 
to  each  other.  It  is  apt  to  be  forgotten  that  the  magnitudes 
of  different  things  can  be  compared  quantitatively,  only  when 
those  magnitudes  are  expressed  in  terms  of  the  same  unit.  It 
is  only  as  expressions  of  such  a  unit  that  they  are  of  the  same 
denomination,  and  therefore  commensurable.^ 

Whether  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat  or  =  20  coats  or  =  x 

1  The  few  economists,  amongst  whom  is  S.  Bailey,  who  have  occupied  themselves 
with  the  analysis  of  the  form  of  value,  have  been  unable  to  arrive  at  any  result,  first, 
because  they  confuse  the  form  of  value  with  value  itself  ;  and  second,  because,  under 
the  coarse  influence  of  the  practical  bourgeois,  they  exclusively  give  their  attention  to 
the  quantitative  aspect  of  the  question.  "The  command  of  quantity  ... 
constitutes  value."  ("Money  and  its  Vicissitudes."  London,  1837.  p.  11.  By  S.. 
Bailey.) 

B 


1 8  Capitalist  Production. 

coats — that  is,  whether  a  given  quantity  of  linen  is  worth  few 
or  many  coats,  every  such  statement  implies  that  the  linen  and 
coats,  as  magnitudes  of  value,  are  expressions  of  the  same  unit, 
things  of  the  same  kind.  Linen  =  coat  is  the  basis  of  the 
equation. 

But  the  two  commodities  whose  identity  of  quality  is  thus 
assumed,  do  not  play  the  same  part.  It  is  only  the  value  of 
the  linen  that  is  expressed.  And  how  ?  By  its  reference  to 
the  coat  as  its  equivalent,  as  something  that  can  be  exchanged 
for  it.  In  this  relation  the  coat  is  the  mode  of  existence  of 
value,  is  value  embodied,  for  only  as  such  is  it  the  same  as  the 
linen.  On  the  other  hand,  the  linen's  own  value  comes  to  the 
front,  receives  independent  expression  ;  for  it  is  only  as  being 
value  that  it  is  comparable  with  the  coat  as  a  thing  of  equal 
value,  or  exchangeable  with  the  coat.  To  borrow  an  illustra- 
tion from  chemistry,  butyric  acid  is  a  different  substance  from 
propyl  formate.  Yet  both  are  made  up  of  the  same  chemical 
substances,  carbon  (C),  hydrogen  (H),  and  oxygen  (0),  and 
that,  too,  in  like  proportions — namely,  C4H8O2.  If  now  we 
equate  butyric  acid  to  propyl  formate,  then,  in  the  first  place, 
propyl  formate  would  be,  in  this  relation,  merely  a  form  of 
existence  of  C4H8O2;  and  in  the  second  place,  we  should  be 
stating  that  butyric  acid  also  consists  of  C4H8O2.  Therefore, 
by  thus  equating  the  two  substances,  expression  would  be  given 
to  their  chemical  composition,  while  their  different  physical 
forms  would  be  neglected. 

If  we  say  that,  as  values,  commodities  are  mere  congelations 
of  human  labour,  we  reduce  them  by  our  analysis,  it  is  true,  to 
the  abstraction,  value  ;  but  we  ascribe  to  this  value  no  form 
apart  from  their  bodily  form.  It  is  otherwise  in  the  value 
relation  of  one  commodity  to  another.  Here,  the  one  stands 
forth  in  its  character  of  value  by  reason  of  its  relation  to  the 
other. 

By  making  the  coat  the  equivalent  of  the  linen,  we  equate 
ihe  labour  embodied  in  the  former  to  that  in  the  latter.  Now, 
it  is  true  that  the  tailoring,  which  makes  the  coat,  is  concrete 
labour  of  a  different  sort  from  the  weaving  which  makes  the 
iinen.     But  the  act  of  equating  it  to  the  weaving,  reduces  the 


Commodities.  1 9 

tailoring  to  that  which  is  really  equal  in  the  two  kinds  of 
labour,  to  their  common  character  of  human  labour.  In  this 
roundabout  way,  then,  the  fact  is  expressed,  that  weaving  also, 
in  so  far  as  it  weaves  value,  has  nothing  to  distinguish  it  from 
tailoring,  and,  consequently,  is  abstract  human  labour.  It  is 
the  expression  of  equivalence  between  different  sorts  of  com- 
modities that  alone  brings  into  relief  the  specific  character  of 
value -creating  labour,  and  this  it  does  by  actually  reducing 
the  different  varieties  of  labour  embodied  in  the  different 
kinds  of  commodities  to  their  common  quality  of  human  labour 
in  the  abstract.^ 

There  is,  however,  something  else  required  beyond  the 
expression  of  the  specific  character  of  the  labour  of  which  the 
value  of  the  linen  consists.  Human  labour-power  in  motion, 
or  human  labour,  creates  value,  but  is  not  itself  value.  It 
becomes  value  only  in  its  congealed  state,  when  embodied  in 
the  form  of  some  object.  In  order  to  express  the  value  of  the 
linen  as  a  congelation  of  human  labour,  that  value  must  be 
expressed  as  having  objective  existence,  as  being  a  something 
materially  different  from  the  linen  itself,  and  yet  a  something 
common  to  the  linen  and  all  other  commodities.  The  problem 
is  already  solved. 

When  occupying  the  position  of  equivalent  in  the  equation 
of  value,  the  coat  ranks  qualitatively  as  the  equal  of  the  linen, 
as  something  of  the  same  kind,  because  it  is  value.  In  this  posi- 
tion it  is  a  thing  in  which  we  see  nothing  but  value,  or  whose 
palpable  bodily  form  represents  value.  Yet  the  coat  itself,  the 
body  of  the  commodity,  coat,  is  a  mere  use-value.  A  coat  as 
such  no  more  tells  us  it  is  value,  than  does  the  first  piece  of 
linen  we  take  hold  of.     This  shows  that  when  placed  in  value 

1  The  celebrated  Franklin,  one  of  the  first  economists,  after  Wm.  Petty,  who  saw 
tlirough  the  nature  of  value,  says:  "Trade  in  general  being  nothing  else  but  the 
exchange  of  labour  for  labour,  the  value  of  all  things  is  ...  .  most  justly 
measured  by  labour."  (The  works  of  B.  Franklin,  &c.,  edited  by  Sparks.  Boston, 
1836,  Vol.  II.,  p.  267.)  Franklin  is  unconscious  that  by  estimating  the  value  of 
everything  in  labour,  he  makes  abstraction  from  any  difference  in  the  sorts  of  labour 
exchanged,  and  thus  reduces  them  all  to  equal  human  labour.  But  although 
ignorant  of  this,  yet  he  says  it.  He  speaks  first  of  "the  one  labour,"  then  of  "the 
other  labour,"  and  finally  of  "labour  "  without  further  qualification,  as  the  substance 
of  the  value  of  everytliing. 


1 


20  Capitalist  Production. 

relation  to  the  linen,  the  coat  signifies  more  than  when  out  of 
that  relation,  just  as  many  a  man  strutting  about  in  a  gorgeous 
uniform  counts  for  more  than  when  in  mufti. 

In  the  production  of  the  coat,  human  labour-power,  in  the 
shape  of  tailoring,  must  have  been  actually  expended.  Human 
labour  is  therefore  accumulated  in  it.  In  this  aspect  the  coat  is 
a  depository  of  value,  but  though  worn  to  a  thread,  it  does  not 
let  this  fact  show  through.  And  as  equivalent  of  the  linen  in 
the  value  equation,  it  exists  under  this  aspect  alone,  counts 
therefore  as  embodied  value,  as  a  body  that  is  value.  A^  for 
instance,  cannot  be  "your  majesty"  to  B,  unless  at  the  same 
time  majesty  in  B's  eyes  assumes  the  bodily  form  of  A,  and, 
what  is  more,  with  every  new  father  of  the  people,  changes  its 
features,  hair,  and  many  other  things  besides. 

Hence,  in  the  value  equation,  in  which  the  coat  is  the  equiva- 
lent of  the  linen,  the  coat  officiates  as  the  form  of  value.  The 
value  of  the  commodity  linen  is  expressed  by  the  bodily  form  of 
the  commodity  coat ;  the  value  of  one  by  the  use-value  of  the 
other.  As  a  use- value,  the  linen  is  something  palpably  dif- 
ferent from  the  coat ;  as  value,  it  is  the  same  as  the  coat,  and 
now  has  the  appearance,  of  a  coat.  Thus  the  linen  acquires 
a  value  form  different  from  its  physical  form.  The  fact  that  it 
is  value,  is  made  manifest  by  its  equality  with  the  coat,  just  as 
the  sheep's  nature  of  a  Christian  is  shown  in  his  resemblance 
to  the  Lamb  of  God. 

We  see,  then,  ail  that  our  analysis  of  the  value  of  commo- 
dities has  already  told  us,  is  told  us  by  the  linen  itself,  so  soon 
as  it  comes  into  communication  with  another  commodity,  the 
coat.  Only  it  betrays  its  thoughts  in  that  language  with 
which  alone  it  is  familiar,  the  language  of  commodities.  In 
order  to  tell  us  that  its  own  value  is  created  by  labour  in  its 
abstract  character  of  human  labour,  it  says  that  the  coat,  in  so 
far  as  it  is  worth  as  much  as  the  linen,  and  therefore  is  value, 
consists  of  the  same  labour  as  the  linen.  In  order  to  inform 
us  that  its  sublime  reality  as  value  is  not  the  same  as  its  buck- 
ram body,  it  says  that  value  has  the  appearance  of  a  coat,  and 
consequently  that  so  far  as  the  linen  is  value,  it  and  the  coat 
are  as  like  as  two  peas.     We  may  here  remark,  that  the  Ian- 


Commodities,  2 1 

guage  of  commodities  has,  besides  Hebrew,  many  other  more  or 
]ess  correct  dialects.  The  German  "  werthsein,"  to  be  worth, 
for  instance,  expresses  in  a  less  striking  manner  than  the 
Romance  verbs  "  valere,"  "  valer,"  "  valoir,"  that  the  equating  of 
commodity  B  to  commodity  A,  is  commodity  A's  own,  mode  of 
expressing  its  value.     Paris  vaut  bien  une  messe. 

By  means,  therefore,  of  the  value  relation  expressed  in  our 
equation,  the  bodily  form  of  commodity  B  becomes  the  value 
form  of  commodity  A,  or  the  body  of  commodity  B  acts  as  a 
mirror  to  the  value  of  commodity  A.^  By  putting  itself  in  re- 
lation with  commodity  B,  as  value  in  jjroprid  persond,  as  the 
matter  of  which  human  labour  is  made  up,  the  commodity  A 
converts  the  value  in  use,  B,  into  the  substance  in  which  to 
express  its,  A's,  own  value.  The  value  of  A,  thus  expressed  in 
the  use- value  of  B,  has  taken  the  form  of  relative  value. 

(b.)  Quantitative  determination  of  Relative  value. 

Every  commodity,  whose  value  it  is  intended  to  express,  is  a 
useful  object  of  given  quantity,  as  15  bushels  of  corn,  or  100 
lbs.  of  coffee.  And  a  given  quantity  of  any  commodity  con- 
tains a  definite  quantity  of  human  labour.  The  value-form 
must  therefore  not  only  express  value  generally,  but  also  value 
in  definite  quantity.  Therefore,  in  the  value  relation  of  com- 
modity A  to  commodity  B,  of  the  linen  to  the  coat,  not  only  is 
the  latter,  as  value  in  general,  made  the  equal  in  quality  of  the 
linen,  but  a  definite  quantity  of  coat  (1  coat)  is  made  the 
equivalent  of  a  definite  quantity  (20  yards)  of  linen. 

The  equation,  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat,  or  20  yards  of  linen 
are  worth  one  coat,  implies  that  the  same  quantity  of  value- 
substance  (congealed  labour)  is  embodied  in  both  ;  that  the 
two  commodities  have  each  cost  the  same  amount  of  labour  or 
the  same  quantity  of  labour  time.  But  the  labour  time 
necessary  for  the  production  of  20  yards  of  linen  or  1  coat 

1  In  a  sort  of  way,  it  is  with  man  as  with  commodities.  Since  he  comes  into  the 
world  neither  with  a  looking  glass  in  his  hand,  nor  as  a  Fichtian  philosopher,  to  whom 
*'  I  am  I  "  is  sufficient,  man  first  sees  and  recognises  himself  in  other  men.  Peter  only 
establishes  his  own  identity  as  a  man  by  first  comparing  himself  with  Paul  as  being 
•f  like  kind.  And  thereby  Paul,  just  as  he  stands  in  his  Pauline  personality,  be- 
comes to  Peter  the  type  of  the  genus  homo. 


22  Capitalist  Production, 

varies  with  every  change  in  the  productiveness  of  weaving  or 
tailoring.  We  have  now  to  consider  the  influence  of  such 
changes  on  the  quantitative  aspect  of  the  relative  expression  of 
valine. 

I.  Let  the  value  of  the  linen  vary/  that  of  the  coat  remaining 
constant.  If,  say  in  consequence  of  the  exhaustion  of  flax- 
growing  soil,  the  labour  time  necessary  for  the  production  of 
the  linen  be  doubled,  the  value  of  the  linen  will  also  be  doubled. 
Instead  of  the  equation,  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat,  we  should 
have  20  yards  of  linen  =:  2  coats,  since  1  coat  would  now  con- 
tain only  half  the  labour  time  embodied  in  20  yards  of  linen. 
If,  on  the  other  hand,  in  consequence,  say,  of  improved  looms, 
this  labour  time  be  reduced  by  one  half,  the  value  of  the  linen 
would  fall  by  one  half.  Consequently,  we  should  have  20 
yards  of  linen  =  J  coat.  The  relative  value  of  commodity  A, 
^.^.,  its  value  expressed  in  commodity  B,  rises  and  falls  directly 
as  the  value  of  A,  the  value  of  B  being  supposed  constant. 

II.  Let  the  value  of  the  linen  remain  constant,  while  the 
value  of  the  coat  varies.  If,  under  these  circumstances,  in 
consequence,  for  instance,  of  a  poor  crop  of  wool,  the  labour 
time  necessary  for  the  production  of  a  coat  becomes  doubled, 
we  have  instead  of  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat,  20  yards  of  linen 
=  \  coat.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  value  of  the  coat  sinks 
by  one  half,  then  20  yards  of  linen  =^  2  coats.  Hence,  if  the 
value  of  commodity  A  remain  constant,  its  relative  value  ex- 
pressed in  commodity  B  rises  and  falls  inversely  as  the  value 
ofB. 

If  we  compare  the  different  cases  in  I.  and  II.,  we  see  that 
the  same  change  of  magnitude  in  relative  value  may  arise  from 
totally  opposite  causes.  Thus,  the  equation,  20  yards  of  linen 
=  1  coat,  becomes  20  yards  of  linen  =-  2  coats,  either,  because,, 
the  value  of  the  linen  has  doubled,  or  because  the  value  of  the 
coat  has  fallen  by  one  half  ;  and  it  becomes  20  yards  of  linen 
=;  \  coat,  either,  because  the  value  of  the  linen  has  fallen  by 
one  half,  or  because  the  value  of  the  coat  has  doubled. 

HI.  Let  the  quantities  of  labour  time   respectively  neces- 

1  Value  is  here,  as  occasionally  in  the  preceding  pages,  used  in  the  sense  of  valu& 
determined  as  to  quantity,  or  of  magnitude  of  value. 


Commodities.  23 

sary  for  the  production  of  the  linen  and  the  coat  vary  sim- 
ultaneously in  the  same  direction  and  in  the  same  proportion. 
In  this  case  20  yards  of  linen  continue  equal  to  1  coat,  however 
much  their  values  may  have  altered.  Their  change  of  value  is 
seen  as  soon  as  they  are  compared  with  a  third  commodity, 
whose  value  has  remained  constant.  If  the  values  of  all  com- 
modities rose  or  fell  simultaneously,  and  in  the  same  proportion, 
their  relative  values  would  remain  unaltered.  Their  real 
change  of  value  would  appear  from  the  diminished  or  increased 
quantity  of  commodities  produced  in  a  given  time. 

IV.  The  labour  time  respectively  necessary  for  the  produc- 
tion of  the  linen  and  the  coat,  and  therefore  the  value  of  these 
commodities  may  simultaneously  vary  in  the  same  direction, 
but  at  unequal  rates,  or  in  opposite  directions,  or  in  other 
ways.  The  effect  of  all  these  possible  different  variations,  on 
the  relative  value  of  a  commodity,  may  be  deduced  from  the 
results  of  I.,  II.,  and  III. 

Thus  real  changes  in  the  magnitude  of  value  are  neither 
unequivocally  nor  exhaustively  reflected  in  their  relative 
expression,  that  is,  in  the  equation  expressing  the  magnitude 
of  relative  value.  The  relative  value  of  a  commodity  may 
vary,  although  its  value  remains  constant.  Its  relative  value 
may  remain  constant,  although  its  value  varies;  and  finally, 
simultaneous  variations  in  the  magnitude  of  value  and  in  that 
of  its  relative  expression  by  no  means  necessarily  correspond 
in  amount.  ^ 

1  This  incongruity  between  the  magnitude  of  value  and  its  relative  expression  has, 
with  customary  ingenuity,  been  exploited  by  vulgar  economists.  For  example — 
"Once  admit  that  A  falls,  because  B,  with  which  it  is  exchanged,  rises,  while  no  less 
labour  is  bestowed  in  the  meantime  on  A,  and  your  general  principle  of  value  falls  to 
the  ground.  .  .  .  If  he  [Ricardo]  allowed  that  when  A  rises  in  value  relatively  to 
B,  B  falls  in  value  relatively  to  A,  he  cut  away  the  ground  on  which  he  rested  his 
grand  proi^osition,  that  the  value  of  a  commodity  is  ever  determined  by  the  labour 
embodied  in  it ;  for  if  a  change  in  the  cost  of  A  alters  not  only  its  own  value  in  rela- 
tion to  B,  for  which  it  is  exchanged,  but  also  the  value  of  B  relatively  to  that  of  A, 
though  no  change  has  taken  place  in  the  quantity  of  labour  to  produce  B,  then  not 
only  the  doctrine  falls  to  the  ground  which  asserts  that  the  quantity  of  labour 
bestowed  on  an  article  regulates  its  value,  but  also  that  which  affirms  the  cost  of  an 
article  to  regulate  its  value."  (J.  Broadhurst:  Political  Economy,  London,  1842,  p.  11 
and  14.) 

Mr.  Broadhurst  might  just  as  well  say :  consider  the  fractions  \%^  i^,  -{^^^  &c., 
the  number  10  remains  unchanged,  and  yet  its  proportional  magnitude,  its  magnitude 


24  Capitalist  Production, 

3.  The  Equivalent  form  of  value. 

We  have  seen  that  commodity  A  (the  linen),  by  expressing 
its  value  in  the  use- value  of  a  commodity  differing  in  kind 
(the  coat),  at  the  same  time  impresses  upon  the  latter  a  specific 
form  of  value,  namely  that  of  the  equivalent.  The  commodity 
linen  manifests  its  quality  of  having  a  value  by  the  fact  that 
the  coat,  without  having  assumed  a  value  form  different  from 
its  bodily  form,  is  equated  to  the  linen.  The  fact  that  the 
latter  therefore  has  a  value  is  expressed  by  saying  that  the 
coat  is  directly  exchangeable  with  it.  Therefore,  when  we  say 
that  a  commodity  is  in  the  equivalent  form,  we  express  the 
fact  that  it  is  directly  exchangeable  with  other  commodities. 

When  one  commodity,  such  as  a  coat,  serves  as  the  equivalent 
of  another,  such  as  linen,  and  coats  consequently  acquire  the 
characteristic  property  of  being  directly  exchangeable  with 
linen,  we  are  far  from  knowing  in  what  proportion  the  two  are 
exchangeable.  The  value  of  the  linen  being  given  in  magni- 
tude, that  proportion  depends  on  the  value  of  the  coat. 
Whether  the  coat  serves  as  the  equivalent  and  the  linen  as 
relative  value,  or  the  linen  as  the  equivalent  and  the  coat  as 
relative  value,  the  magnitude  of  the  coat's  value  is  determined, 
independently  of  its  value  form,  by  the  labour  time  necessary 
for  its  production.  But  whenever  the  coat  assumes  in  the 
equation  of  value,  the  position  of  equivalent,  its  value  acquires 
no  quantitative  expression ;  on  the  contrary,  the  commodity 
coat  now  figures  only  as  a  definite  quantity  of  some  article. 

For  instance,  40  yards  of  linen  are  worth — what  ?  2  coats. 
Because  the  commodity  coat  here  plays  the  part  of  equivalent, 
because  the  use-value  cca\  as  opposed  to  the  linen,  figures  as 
an  embodiment  of  value,  therefore  a  definite  number  of  coats 
suffices  to  express  the  definite  quantity  of  value  in  the  linen. 
Two  coats  may  therefore  express  the  quantity  of  value  of  40 
yards  of  linen,  but  they  can  never  express  the  quantity  of  their 
own  value.     A  superficial  observation  of  this  fact,  namely,  that 

relatively  to  the  mimbers  20,  50,  100,  &c.,  continually  diminishes.  Therefore  the 
great  principle  that  the  magnitude  of  a  whole  number,  such  as  10,  is  "  regulated  "  by 
the  number  of  times  unity  is  contained  in  it,  falls  to  the  ground. — [The  author  ex- 
plains in  section  4  of  this  chapter,  p.  62,  note  2,  what  he  understands  by  "Vulgar 
Economy."— Ed.] 


Com  modules.  2  5 

in  the  equation  of  value,  the  equivalent  figures  exclusively  as 
a  simple  quantity  of  some  article,  of  some  use-value,  has  misled 
Bailey,  as  also  many  others,  both  before  and  after  him,  into 
vseeing,  in  the  expression  of  value,  merely  a  quantitative  relation. 
The  truth  being,  that  when  a  commodity  acts  as  equivalent, 
no  quantitative  determination  of  its  value  is  expressed. 

The  first  peculiarity  that  strikes  us,  in  considering  the  form 
of  the  equivalent,  is  this  :  use- value  becomes  the  form  of  mani- 
festation, the  phenomenal  form  of  its  opposite,  value. 

The  bodily  form  of  the  commodity  becomes  its  value  form. 
But,  mark  well,  that  this  quid  pro  quo  exists  in  the  case  of  any 
commodity  B,  only  when  some  other  commodity  A  enters  into 
a  value  relation  with  it,  and  then  only  within  the  limits  of  this 
relation.  Since  no  commodity  can  stand  in  the  relation  of 
equivalent  to  itself,  and  thus  turn  its  own  bodily  shape  into 
the  expression  of  its  own  value,  every  commodity  is  compelled 
to  choose  some  other  commodity  for  its  equivalent,  and  to  accept 
the  use-value,  that  is  to  say,  the  bodily  shape  of  that  other 
commodity  as  the  form  of  its  own  value. 

One  of  the  measures  that  we  apply  to  commodities  as  material 
substances,  as  use-values,  will  serve  to  illustrate  this  point.  A 
•sugar-loaf  being  a  body,  is  heavy,  and  therefore  has  weight : 
but  we  can  neither  see  nor  touch  this  weight.  We  then  take 
various  pieces  of  iron,  whose  weight  has  been  determined 
beforehand.  The  iron,  as  iron,  is  no  more  the  form  of  manifes- 
tation of  weight,  than  is  the  sugar-loaf.  Nevertheless,  in  order 
to  express  the  sugar-loaf  as  so  much  weight,  we  put  it  into  a 
weight-relation  with  the  iron.  In  this  relation,  the  iron 
officiates  as  a  body  representing  nothing  but  weight.  A  certain 
quantity  of  iron  therefore  serves  as  the  measure  of  the  weight 
of  the  sugar,  and  represents,  in  relation  to  the  sugar-loaf, 
weight  embodied,  the  form  of  manifestation  of  weight.  This 
part  is  played  by  the  iron  only  within  this  relation,  into  which 
the  sugar  or  any  other  body,  whose  weight  has  to  be  determined, 
enters  with  the  iron.  Were  they  not  both  heavy,  they  could 
not  enter  into  this  relation,  and  the  one  could  therefore  not 
serve  as  the  expression  of  the  weight  of  the  other.  When  we 
throw  both  into  the  scales,  we  see  in  reality,  that  as  weight 


26  Capitalist  Prodtiction. 

they  are  both  the  same,  and  that,  therefore,  when  taken  in 
proper  proportions,  they  have  the  same  weight.  Just  as  the 
substance  iron,  as  a  measure  of  weight,  represents  in  relation 
to  the  sugar-loaf  weight  alone,  so,  in  our  expression  of  value^ 
the  material  object,  coat,  in  relation  to  the  linen,  represents 
value  alone. 

Here,  however,  the  analogy  ceases.  The  iron,  in  the  ex- 
pression of  the  weight  of  the  sugar-loaf,  represents  a  natural  pro- 
perty common  to  both  bodies,  namely  their  weight;  but  the  coat, 
in  the  expression  of  value  of  the  linen,  represents  a  non-natural 
property  of  both,  something  purely  social,  namely,  their  value. 

Since  the  relative  form  of  value  of  a  commodity — the  linen, 
for  example — expresses  the  value  of  that  commodity,  as  being 
something  wholly  different  from  its  substance  and  properties, 
as  being,  for  instance,  coat-like,  we  see  that  this  expression 
itself  indicates  that  some  social  relation  lies  at  the  bottom  of 
it.  With  the  equivalent  form  it  is  just  the  contrary.  The  very 
essence  of  this  form  is  that  the  material  commodity  itself — the 
coat — ^just  as  it  is,  expresses  value,  and  is  endowed  with  the 
form  of  value  by  Nature  itself.  Of  course  this  holds  good  only 
so  long  as  the  value  relation  exists,  in  which  the  coat  stands  in 
the  position  of  equivalent  to  the  linen.^  Since,  however,  the 
properties  of  a  thing  are  not  the  result  of  its  relations  to  other 
things,  but  only  manifest  themselves  in  such  relations,  the 
coat  seems  to  be  endowed  with  its  equivalent  form,  its  property 
of  being  directly  exchangeable,  just  as  much  by  Nature  as  it  is 
endowed  with  the  property  of  being  heavy,  or  the  capacity  to 
keep  us  warm.  Hence  the  enigmatical  character  of  the  equiva- 
lent form  which  escapes  the  notice  of  the  bourgeois  political 
economist,  until  this  form,  completely  developed,  confronts  him 
in  the  shape  of  money.  He  then  seeks  to  explain  away  the 
mystical  character  of  gold  and  silver,  by  substituting  for  them 
less  dazzling  commodities,  and  by  reciting,  with  ever  renewed 
satisfaction,  the  catalogue  of  all  possible  commodities  which  at 
one  time  or  another  have  plaj^ed  the  part  of  equivalent.     He  has 

1  Such  expressions  of  relations  in  general,  called  by  Hegel  reflex-categories,  form  a 
very  curious  class.  For  instance,  one  man  is  king  only  because  other  men  stand  in 
the  relation  of  subjects  to  him.  They,  on  the  contrary,  imagine  that  they  are  sub- 
jects because  he  is  king. 


Commodities.  27 

not  the  least  suspicion  that  the  most  simple  expression  of  value, 
such  as  20  yds.  of  linen  =  1  coat,  already  propounds  the  riddle 
of  the  equivalent  form  for  our  solution. 

The  body  of  the  commodity  that  serves  as  the  equivalent, 
figures  as  the  materialisation  of  human  labour  in  the  abstract, 
and  is  at  the  same  time  the  product  of  some  specifically  useful 
concrete  labour.  This  concrete  labour  becomes,  therefore,  the 
medium  for  expressing  abstract  human  labour.  If  on  the 
one  hand  the  coat  ranks  as  nothing  but  the  embodiment  of 
abstract  human  labour,  so,  on  the  other  hand,  the  tailoring 
which  is  actually  embodied  in  it,  counts  as  nothing  but  the 
form  under  which  that  abstract  labour  is  realised.  In  the  ex- 
pression of  value  of  the  linen,  the  utility  of  the  tailoring  con- 
sists, not  in  making  clothes,  but  in  making  an  object,  which  we 
at  once  recognise  to  be  Value,  and  therefore  to  be  a  congelation 
of  labour,  but  of  labour  indistinguishable  from  that  realised  in 
the  value  of  the  linen.  In  order  to  act  as  such  a  mirror  of 
value,  the  labour  of  tailoring  must  reflect  nothing  besides  its 
own  abstract  quality  of  being  human  labour  generally. 

In  tailoring,  as  well  as  in  weaving,  human  labour-power  is 
expended.  Both,  therefore,  possess  the  general  property  of 
being  human  labour,  and  may,  therefore,  in  certain  cases,  such 
as  in  the  production  of  value,  have  to  be  considered  under 
this  aspect  alone.  There  is  nothing  mysterious  in  this.  But 
in  the  expression  of  value  there  is  a  complete  turn  of  the 
tables.  For  instance,  how  is  the  fact  to  be  expressed  that 
weaving  creates  the  value  of  the  linen,  not  by  virtue  of  being- 
weaving,  as  such,  but  by  reason  of  its  general  property  of  being 
human  labour  ?  Simply  by  opposing  to  weaving  that  other 
particular  form  of  concrete  labour  (in  this  instance  tailoring)^ 
which  produces  the  equivalent  of  the  product  of  weaving. 
Just  as  the  coat  in  its  bodily  form  became  a  direct  expression 
of  value,  so  now  does  tailoring,  a  concrete  form  of  labour, 
appear  as  the  direct  and  palpable  embodiment  of  human  labour 
generally. 

Hence,  the  second  peculiarity  of  the  equivalent  form  is,  that 
concrete  labour  becomes  the  form  under  which  its  opposite, 
abstract  human  labour,  manifests  itself. 


28  Capitalist  Production. 

But  befjause  this  concrete  labour,  tailoring  in  our  case,  ranks 
as,  and  is  directly  identified  with,  undifferentiated  human 
labour,  it  also  ranks  as  identical  with  any  other  sort  of  labour, 
and  therefore  with  that  embodied  in  the  linen.  Consequently, 
although,  like  all  other  commodity-producing  labour,  it  is  the 
labour  of  private  individuals,  yet,  at  the  same  time,  it  ranks  as 
labour  directly  social  in  its  character.  This  is  the  reason  why 
it  results  in  a  product  directly  exchangeable  with  other  com- 
modities. We  have  then  a  third  peculiarity  of  the  Equivalent 
form,  namely,  that  the  labour  of  private  individuals  takes  the 
form  of  its  opposite,  labour  directly  social  in  its  form. 

The  two  latter  peculiarities  of  the  Equivalent  form  will 
become  more  intelligible  if  we  go  back  to  the  great  thinker 
who  was  the  first  to  analyse  so  many  forms,  whether  of 
thought,  society,  or  nature,  and  amongst  them  also  the  form  of 
value.     I  mean  Aristotle. 

In  the  first  place,  he  clearly  enunciates  that  the  money  form 
of  commodities  is  only  the  further  development  of  the  simple 
form  of  value — i.e.y  of  the  expression  of  the  value  of  one  com- 
modity in  some  other  commodity  taken  at  random ;  for  he  says — 
5  beds   =   1   house    {>t\hcti  T^n  ktri  oUtas)    is    not    to    be 

distinguished  from 
5  beds  =  so  much  money. 

{xXiven  'Tivrt  6.vtI  .    .    .    ofou  aX  Tivrt  KXlvai') 

He  further  sees  that  the  value  relation  which  gives  rise  to 
this  expression  makes  it  necessary  that  the  house  should  quali- 
tatively be  made  the  equal  of  the  bed,  and  that,  Avithout  such 
an  equalisation,  these  two  clearly  different  things  could  not  be 
compared  with  each  other  as  commensurable  quantities.  "  Ex- 
change," he  says,  "cannot  take  place  without  equality,  and 
equality  not  without  commensurability "  (oiir  itrerni  /^h  oiitrns 
evfjt.fjurp'ias).  Hcrc,  howcvcr,  he  comes  to  a  stop,  and  gives 
up  the  further  analysis  of  the  form  of  value.  "  It  is, 
however,  in  reality,  impossible  (rl^  f^h  olv  aXnhU  a.'^vvarov),  that 
such  unlike  things  can  be  commensurable " — i.e.,  qualita- 
tively equal.  Such  an  equalisation  can  only  be  something 
foreign  to  their  real  nature,  consequently  only  "  a  make-shift 
for  practical  purposes." 


Commodities,  29 

Aristotle  therefore,  himself,  tells  us,  what  barred  the  way  to 
his  further  analysis ;  it  was  the  absence  of  anj'  concept  of 
value.  What  is  that  equal  something,  that  common  substance, 
which  admits  of  the  value  of  the  beds  being  expressed  by  a 
house  ?  Such  a  thing,  in  truth,  cannot  exist,  says  Aristotle. 
And  why  not  ?  Compared  with  the  beds,  the  house  does  re- 
present something  equal  to  them,  in  so  far  as  it  represents  what 
is  really  equal,  both  in  the  beds  and  the  house.  And  that  is — 
human  labour. 

There  was,  however,  an  important  fact  which  prevented 
Aristotle  from  seeing  that,  to  attribute  value  to  commodities,  is 
merely  a  mode  of  expressing  all  labour  as  equal  human  labour, 
and  consequently  as  labour  of  equal  quality.  Greek  society 
was  founded  upon  slavery,  and  had,  therefore,  for  its  natural 
basis,  the  inequality  of  men  and  of  their  labour  powers.  The 
secret  of  the  expression  of  value,  namely,  that  all  kinds  of 
labour  are  equal  and  equivalent,  because,  and  so  far  as  they 
are  human  labour  in  general,  cannot  be  deciphered,  until  the 
notion  of  human  equality  has  already  acquired  the  fixity  of  a 
popular  prejudice.  This,  however,  is  possible  only  in  a  society 
in  which  the  great  mass  of  the  produce  of  labour  takes  the  form 
of  commodities,  in  which,  consequently,  the  dominant  relation 
between  man  and  man,  is  that  of  owners  of  commodities.  The 
brilliancy  of  Aristotle's  genius  is  shown  by  this  alone,  that  he 
discovered,  in  the  expression  of  the  value  of  commodities,  a 
relation  of  equality.  The  peculiar  conditions  of  the  society  in 
which  he  lived,  alone  prevented  him  from  discovering  what, 
'*  in  truth,"  was  at  the  bottom  of  this  equality. 

4.  The  Elementary  fovm  of  value  considered  as  a  whole. 

The  elementary  form  of  value  of  a  commodity  is  contained 
in  the  equation,  expressing  its  value  relation  to  another  com- 
modity of  a  different  kind,  or  in  its  exchange  relation  to  the 
same.  The  value  of  commodity  A,  is  qualitatively  expressed, 
by  the  fact  that  commodity  B  is  directly  exchangeable  with  it. 
Its  value  is  quantitatively  expressed  by  the  fact,  that  a  definite 
quantity  of  B  is  exchangeable  with  a  definite  quantity  of  A. 
Iq  other  words,  the  value  of  a  commodity  obtains  independent 


30  Capitalist  Prodtiction. 

and  definite  expression,  by  taking  the  form  of  exchange  value. 
When,  at  the  beginning  of  this  chapter,  we  said,  in  common 
parlance,  that  a  commodity  is  both  a  use-value  and  an  ex- 
change value,  we  were,  accurately  speaking,  wrong.  A  com- 
modity is  a  use- value  or  object  of  utility,  and  a  value.  It 
manifests  itself  as  this  two-fold  thing,  that  it  is,  as  soon  as  its 
value  assumes  an  independent  form — viz.,  the  form  of  exchange 
value.  It  never  assumes  this  form  when  isolated,  but  only 
when  placed  in  a  value  or  exchange  relation  with  another 
commodity  of  a  different  kind.  When  once  we  know  this, 
such  a  mode  of  expression  does  no  harm ;  it  simply  serves  as 
an  abbreviation. 

Our  analysis  has  shown,  that  the  form  or  expression  of  the 
value  of  a  commodity  originates  in  the  nature  of  value,  and 
not  that  value  and  its  magnitude  originate  in  the  mode  of 
their  expression  as  exchange  value.  This,  however,  is  the 
delusion  as  well  of  the  mercantilists  and  their  recent  revivors, 
Ferrier,  Ganilh,^  and  others,  as  also  of  their  antipodes,  the 
modern  bagmen  of  Free  Trade,  such  as  Bastiat.  The  mercan- 
tilists lay  special  stress  on  the  qualitative  aspect  of  the 
expression  of  value,  and  consequently  on  the  equivalent  form 
of  commodities,  which  attains  its  full  perfection  in  money. 
The  modern  hawkers  of  Free  Trade,  who  must  get  rid  of  their 
article  at  any  price,  on  the  other  hand,  lay  most  stress  on  the 
quantitative  aspect  of  the  relative  form  of  value.  For  them 
there  consequently  exists  neither  value,  nor  magnitude  of 
value,  anywhere  except  in  its  expression  by  means  of  the 
exchange  relation  of  commodities,  that  is,  in  the  daily  list  of 
prices  current.  MacLeod,  who  has  taken  upon  himself  to 
dress  up  the  confused  ideas  of  Lombard  Street  in  the  most 
learned  finery,  is  a  successful  cross  between  the  superstitious 
mercantilists,  and  the  enlightened  Free  Trade  bagmen. 

A  close  scrutiny  of  the  expression  of  the  value  of  A  in  terms 
of  B,  contained  in-  the  equation  expressing  the  value  relation  of 
A  to  B,  has  shown  us  that,  within  that  relation,  the  bodily  form 

1  F.  L.  A.  Ferrier,  sous-inspecteur  des  douanes,  "Du  gouvernement  consider^  dans 
ses  rapports  avec  le  commerce,"  Paris,  1805;  and  Charles  Ganilh,  "Des  Systdmes 
d'Economie  politique,"  2nd  ed.,  Paris,  1821. 


Commodities.  31 

of  A  figures  only  as  a  use- value,  the  bodily  form  of  B  only  as 
the  form  or  aspect  of  value.  The  opposition  or  contrast 
existing  internally  in  each  commodity  between  use- value  and 
value,  is,  therefore,  made  evident  externally  by  two  com- 
modities being  placed  in  such  relation  to  each  other,  that  the 
commodity  whose  value  it  is  sought  to  express,  figures  directly 
as  a  mere  use-value,  while  the  commodity  in  which  that  value 
is  to  be  expressed,  figures  directly  as  mere  exchange  value. 
Hence  the  elementary  form  of  value  of  a  commodity  is  the 
elementary  form  in  which  the  contrast  contained  in  that 
■commodity,  between  use- value  and  value,  becomes  apparent. 

Every  product  of  labour  is,  in  all  states  of  society,  a  use- 
value  ;  but  it  is  only  at  a  definite  historical  epoch  in  a  society's 
development  that  such  a  product  becomes  a  commodity,  viz., 
at  the  epoch  when  the  labour  spent  on  the  production  of  a 
useful  article  becomes  expressed  as  one  of  the  objective 
qualities  of  that  article,  i.e.,  as  its  value.  It  therefore  follows 
that  the  elementary  value-form  is  also  the  primitive  form 
under  which  a  product  of  labour  appears  historically  as  a 
-commodity,  and  that  the  gradual  transformation  of  such 
products  into  commodities,  proceeds  pari  passu  with  the 
development  of  the  value  form. 

We  perceive,  at  first  sight,  the  deficiencies  of  the  elementary 
form  of  value  :  it  is  a  mere  germ,  which  must  undergo  a  series 
of  metamorphoses  before  it  can  ripen  into  the  Price-form. 

The  expression  of  the  value  of  commodity  A  in  terms  of  any 
other  commodity  B,  merely  distinguishes  the  value  from  the 
use-value  of  A,  and  therefore  places  A  merely  in  a  relation  of 
exchange  with  a  single  different  commodity,  B ;  but  it  is  still 
far  from  expressing  A's  qualitative  equality,  and  quantitative 
proportionality,  to  all  commodities.  To  the  elementary  relative 
value-form  of  a  commodity,  there  corresponds  the  single  equi- 
valent form  of  one  other  commodity.  Thus,  in  the  relative 
expression  of  value  of  the  linen,  the  coat  assumes  the  form  of 
equivalent,  or  of  being  directly  exchangeable,  only  in  relation 
to  a  single  commodity,  the  linen. 

Nevertheless,  the  elementary  form  of  value  passes  by  an  easy 
transition  into  a  more  comolete  form.     It  is  true  that  by  means 


32  Capitalist  Production. 

of  the  elementary  form,  the  value  of  a  commodity  A,  becomes 
expressed  in  terms  of  one,  and  only  one,  other  commodity^ 
But  that  one  may  be  a  commodity  of  any  kind,  coat,  iron,  com^ 
or  anything  else.  Therefore,  according  as  A  is  placed  in  rela- 
tion with  one  or  the  other,  we  get  for  one  and  the  same  com- 
modity, different  elementary  expressions  of  value.^  The  number 
of  such  possible  expressions  is  limited  only  by  the  number  of 
the  different  kinds  of  commodities  distinct  from  it.  The 
isolated  expression  of  A's  value,  is  therefore  convertible  into  a 
series,  prolonged  to  any  length,  of  the  different  elementary  ex- 
pressions of  that  value. 

B.  Total  or  Expanded  form  of  valite. 

z  Com.  A=u  Com.  B  or=v  Com.  C  or=w  Com.  D  or=x  Com. 

E  or=&c. 

(20  yards  of  linen=l  coat  or=10  lb  tea  or=40  lb  coffee  or= 

1  quarter  corn  or=2  ounces  gold  or=|  ton  iron  or=&c.) 

1.  The  Expanded  Relative  form  of  value. 

The  value  of  a  single  commodity,  the  linen,  for  example,  is 
now  expressed  in  terms  of  numberless  other  elements  of  the 
world  of  commodities.  Every  other  commodity  now  becomes 
a  mirror  of  the  linen's  value.^     It  is  thus,  that  for  the  first  time, 

1  In  Homer,  for  instance,  the  value  of  an  article  is  expressed  in  a  series  of  different 
things.     II.  VII.  472-475. 

2  For  this  reason,  we  can  speak  of  the  coat-value  of  the  linen  when  its  value  is  ex- 
pressed in  coats,  or  of  its  corn-value  when  expressed  in  corn,  and  so  on.  Every  such 
expression  tells  us,  that  what  appears  in  the  use-values,  coat,  corn,  &c.,  is  the  value 
of  the  linen.  "  The  value  of  any  commodity  denoting  its  relation  in  exchange,  we 
may  si^eak  of  it  as  .  .  .  corn-value,  cloth-value,  according  to  the  commodity  with 
which  it  is  compared ;  and  hence  there  are  a  tliousand  different  kinds  of  value,  as  many 
kinds  of  value  as  there  are  commodities  in  existence,  and  all  are  equally  real  and 
equally  nominal."  (A  Critical  Dissertation  on  the  Nature,  Measure  and  Causes  of 
Value  :  chiefly  in  reference  to  the  writings  of  Mr.  Ricardo  and  his  followers.  By  the 
author  of  "  Essays  on  the  Formation,  &c.,  of  Opinions."  London,  1825,  p.  39).  S. 
Bailey,  the  author  of  this  anonymous  work,  a  work  which  in  its  day  created  much 
stir  in  England,  fancied  that,  by  thus  pointing  out  the  various  relative  expressions  of 
one  and  the  same  value,  he  had  proved  the  impossibility  of  any  determination  of  the 
concept  of  value.  However  narrow  his  own  views  may  have  been,  yet,  that  he  laid 
his  finger  on  some  serious  defects  in  the  Ricardian  Theory,  is  proved  by  the  animosity 
with  which  he  was  attacked  by  Ricardo's  followers.  See  the  Westminster  Review  for 
example. 


Commodities.  33 

this  value  shows  itself  in  its  true  light  as  a  congelation  of  un- 
differentiated human  labour.  For  the  labour  that  creates  it, 
now  stands  expressly  revealed,  as  labour  that  ranks  equally 
with  every  other  sort  of  human  labour,  no  matter  what  its 
form,  whether  tailoring,  ploughing,  mining,  &c.,  and  no  matter, 
therefore,  whether  it  is  realised  in  coats,  corn,  iron,  or  gold. 
The  linen,  by  virtue  of  the  form  of  its  value,  now  stands  in  a 
social  relation,  no  longer  with  only  one  other  kind  of  com- 
modity, but  with  the  whole  world  of  commodities.  As  a 
commodity,  it  is  a  citizen  of  that  world.  At  the  same  time, 
the  interminable  series  of  value  equations  implies,  that  as  re- 
gards the  value  of  a  commodity,  it  is  a  matter  of  in- 
difference under  what  particular  form,  or  kind,  of  use-value  it 
appears. 

In  the  first  form,  20  yds.  of  linen  =  1  coat,  it  might,  for  ought 
that  otherwise  appears,  be  pure  accident,  that  these  two  com- 
modities are  exchangeable  in  definite  quantities.  In  the  second 
form,  on  the  contrary,  we  perceive  at  once  the  background  that 
determines,  and  is  essentially  different  from,  this  accidental 
appearance.  The  value  of  the  linen  remains  unaltered  in  mag- 
nitude, whether  expressed  in  coats,  coffee,  or  iron,  or  in  num- 
berless different  commodities,  the  property  of  as  many 
different  owners.  The  accidental  relation  between  two  in- 
dividual commodity-owners  disappears.  It  becomes  plain,  that 
it  is  not  the  exchange  of  commodities  which  regulates  the 
magnitude  of  their  value ;  but,  on  the  contrary,  that  it  is  the 
magnitude  of  their  value  which  controls  their  exchange 
proportions. 

2.  The 'particular  Equivalent  form. 

Each  commodity,  such  as,  coat,  tea,  corn,  iron,  &c.,  figures  in 
the  expression  of  value  of  the  linen,  as  an  equivalent,  and,  con- 
sequently, as  a  thing  that  is  value.  The  bodily  form  of  each 
of  these  commodities  figures  now  as  a  particular  equivalent 
form,  one  out  of  many.  In  the  same  way  the  manifold  concrete 
useful  kinds  of  labour,  embodied  in  these  different  commodities,, 
rank  now  as  so  many  different  forms  of  the  realisation,  or  mani-^ 
festation,  of  undifferentiated  human  labour. 

0 


34  Capitalist  Production. 

3.  Defects  of  the  Total  or  Expanded  forrri  of  value. 

In  the  first  place,  the  relative  expression  of  value  is  incomplete 
because  the  series  representing  it  is  interminable.  The  chain 
of  which  each  equation  of  value  is  a  link,  is  liable  at  any 
moment  to  be  lengthened  by  each  new  kind  of  commodity  that 
comes  into  existence  and  furnishes  the  material  for  a  fresh 
expression  of  value.  In  the  second  place,  it  is  a  many- 
coloured  mosaic  of  disparate  and  independent  expressions 
of  value.  And  lastly,  if,  as  must  be  the  case,  the  relative  value 
of  each  commodity  in  turn,  becomes  expressed  in  this  ex- 
panded form,  we  get  for  each  of  them  a  relative  value-form, 
different  in  every  case,  and  consisting  of  an  interminable 
series  of  expressions  of  value.  The  defects  of  the  expanded 
relative-value  form  are  reflected  in  the  corresponding  equiva- 
lent form.  Since  the  bodily  form  of  each  single  commodity  is 
one  particular  equivalent  form  amongst  numberless  others,  we 
have,  on  the  whole,  nothing  but  fragmentary  equivalent  forms, 
each  excluding  the  others.  In  the  same  way,  also,  the  special, 
concrete,  useful  kind  of  labour  embodied  in  each  particular 
equivalent,  is  presented  only  as  a  particular  kind  of  labour, 
and  therefore  not  as  an  exhaustive  representative  of  human 
labour  generally.  The  latter,  indeed,  gains  adequate  manifes- 
tation in  the  totality  of  its  manifold,  particular,  concrete  forms. 
But,  in  that  case,  its  expression  in  an  infinite  series  is  ever 
incomplete  and  deficient  in  unity. 

The  expanded  relative  value-form  is,  however,  nothing  but 
the  sum  of  the  elementary  relative  expressions  or  equations  of 
the  first  kind,  such  as 

20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat 

20  yards  of  linen  =  10  lbs.  of  tea,  etc. 

Each  of  these  implies  the  corresponding  inverted  equation, 
1  coat  =  20  yards  of  linen 
10  lbs.  of  tea  =  20  yards  of  linen,  etc. 

In  fact,  when  a  person  exchanges  his  linen  for  many  other 
commodities,  and  thus  expresses  its  value  in  a  series  of  other 
commodities,  it  necessarily  follows,  that  the  various  owners  of 
the  latter  exchange  them  for  the  linen,  and  consequently  express 


Commodities,  35 

the  value  of  their  various  commodities  in  one  and  the  same 
third  commodity,  the  linen.  If  then,  we  reverse  the  series,  20 
yards  of  linen  :=  1  coat  or  =  10  lbs.  of  tea,  etc.,  that  is  to  say, 
if  we  give  expression  to  the  converse  relation  already  implied 
in  the  series,  we  get, 

(7.  The  General  form  of  value, 
1  coat 

10  lbs.  of  tea 
40  lbs.  of  coffee 

1  quarter  of  corn  )>   —  20  yards  of  linen 

2  ounces  of  gold 
•i-  a  ton  of  iron 
X  com.  A.,  etc. 

1.  l^he  altered  cliaracter  of  the  form  of  value. 

All  commodities  now  express  their  value  (1)  in  an  elementary 
form,  because  in  a  single  commodity;  (2)  with  unity,  because  in 
one  and  the  same  commodity.  This  form  of  value  is  elementary 
and  the  same  for  all,  therefore  general. 

The  forms  A  and  B  were  fit  only  to  express  the  value  of  a 
commodity  as  something  distinct  from  its  use-value  or  material 
form. 

The  first  form.  A,  furnishes  such  equations  as  the  following : — 
1  coat  =  20  yards  of  linen,  10  lbs.  of  tea  =  |  ton  of  iron. 
The  value  of  the  coat  is  equated  to  linen,  that  of  the  tea  to 
iron.  But  to  be  equated  to  linen,  and  again  to  iron,  is  to  be  as 
difierent  as  are  linen  and  iron.  This  form,  it  is  plain,  occurs 
practically  only  in  the  first  beginning,  when  the  products  of 
labour  are  converted  into  commodities  by  accidental  and 
occasional  exchanges. 

The  second  form,  B,  distinguishes,  in  a  more  adequate  manner 
than  the  first,  the  value  of  a  commodity  from  its  use- value ;  for 
the  value  of  the  coat  is  there  placed  in  contrast  under  all 
possible  shapes  with  the  bodily  form  of  the  coat  ;  it  is  equated 
to  linen,  to  iron,  to  tea,  in  short,  to  everything  else,  only  not  to 
itself,  the  coat.  On  the  other  hand,  any  general  expression  of 
value  common  to  all  is  directly  excluded  ;  for,  in  the  equation 
of  value  of  each  commodity,  all  other  commodities  now  appear 


36  Capitalist  Production, 

only  under  the  form  of  equivalents.  The  expanded  form  of 
value  comes  into  actual  existence  for  the  first  time  so  soon  as 
a  particular  product  of  labour,  such  as  cattle,  is  no  longer 
exceptionally,  but  habitually,  exchanged  for  various  other 
commodities. 

The  third  and  lastly  developed  form  expresses  the  values  ol 
the  whole  world  of  commodities  in  terms  of  a  single  commodity 
set  apart  for  the  purpose,  namely,  the  linen,  and  thus  represents 
to  us  their  values  by  means  of  their  equality  with  linen.  The 
value  of  every  commodity  is  now,  by  being  equated  to  linen, 
not  only  differentiated  from  its  own  use-value,  but  from  all 
other  use- values  generally,  and  is,  by  that  very  fact,  expressed 
as  that  which  is  common  to  all  commodities.  By  this  form, 
commodities  are,  for  the  first  time,  effectively  brought  inta 
relation  with  one  another  as  values,  or  made  to  appear  as- 
exchange  values. 

The  two  earlier  forms  either  express  the  value  of  each  com- 
modity in  terms  of  a  single  commodity  of  a  different  kind,  or 
in  a  series  of  many  such  commodities.  In  both  cases,  it  is,  so- 
to  say,  the  special  business  of  each  single  commodity  to  find  an 
expression  for  its  value,  and  this  it  does  without  the  help  of 
the  others.  These  others,  with  respect  to  the  former,  play  the 
passive  parts  of  equivalents.  The  general  form  of  value,  C,. 
results  from  the  joint  action  of  the  whole  world  of  commodities 
and  from  that  alone.  A  commodity  can  acquire  a  general  expres- 
sion of  its  value  only  by  all  other  commodities,  simultaneously 
with  it,  expressing  their  values  in  the  same  equivalent ;  and 
every  new  commodity  must  follow  suit.  It  thus  becomes 
evident  that,  since  the  existence  of  commodities  as  values  is 
purely  social,  this  social  existence  can  be  expressed  by  the 
totality  of  their  social  relations  alone,  and  consequently 
that  the  form  of  their  value  must  be  a  socially  recognised 
form. 

All  commodities  being  eqiiated  to  linen  now  appear  not  only 
as  qualitatively  equal  as  values  generally,  but  also  as  values 
whose  magnitudes  are  capable  of  comparison.  By  expressing 
the  magnitudes  of  their  values  in  one  and  the  same  material, 
the  linen,  those  magnitudes  are  also  compared  with  each  other. 


Co77imodities,  37 

For  instance,  10  lbs.  of  tea  =  20  yards  of  linen,  and  40  lbs.  of 
•coffee  =  20  yards  of  linen.  Therefore,  10  lbs.  of  tea  ==  40  lbs. 
of  coffee.  In  other  words,  there  is  contained  in  1  lb.  of  coffee 
only  one-fourth  as  much  substance  of  value — labour — as  is  con- 
tained in  1  lb.  of  tea. 

The  general  form  of  relative  value,  embracing  the  whole 
world  of  commodities,  converts  the  single  commodity  that  is 
excluded  from  the  rest,  and  made  to  play  the  part  of  equivalent 
— here  the  linen — into  the  universal  equivalent.  The  bodily 
form  of  the  linen  is  now  the  form  assumed  in  common  by  the 
values  of  ail  commodities ;  it  therefore  becomes  directly 
exchangeable  with  all  and  every  of  them.  The  substance 
linen  becomes  the  visible  incarnation,  the  social  chrysalis  state 
of  every  kind  of  human  labour.  Weaving,  which  is  the  labour 
of  certain  private  individuals  producing  a  particular  article,  linen, 
acquires  in  consequence  a  social  character,  the  character  of 
equality  with  all  other  kinds  of  labour.  The  innumerable 
equations  of  which  the  general  form  of  value  is  composed, 
equate  in  turn  the  labour  embodied  in  the  linen  to  that  em- 
bodied in  every  other  commodity,  and  they  thus  convert 
weaving  into  the  general  form  of  manifestation  of  undiffer- 
entiated human  labour.  In  this  manner  the  labour  realised  in 
the  values  of  commodities  is  presented  not  only  under  its 
negative  aspect,  under  which  abstraction  is  made  from  every 
concrete  form  and  useful  property  of  actual  work,  but 
its  own  positive  nature  is  made  to  reveal  itself  expressly. 
The  general  value-form  is  the  reduction  of  all  kinds  of 
actual  labour  to  their  common  character  of  being  human 
labour  generally,  of  being  the  expenditure  of  human  labour 
power. 

The  general  value  form,  which  represents  all  products  of 
labour  as  mere  congelations  of  undifferentiated  human  labour, 
^shows  by  its  very  structure  that  it  is  the  social  resum^  of  the 
world  of  commodities.  That  form  consequently  makes  it 
indisputably  evident  that  in  the  world  of  commodities  the 
character  possessed  by  all  labour  of  being  human  labour 
constitutes  its  specific-  social  character. 


o 


8  Capitalist  Production. 


2.  The  interdependent  development  of  the  Relative  fovvfi  of  valuer 
and  of  the  Equivalent  form. 

The  degree  of  development  of  the  relative  form  of  value 
corresponds  to  that  of  the  equivalent  form.  But  we  must  bear 
in  mind  that  the  development  of  the  latter  is  only  the  expres- 
sion and  result  of  the  development  of  the  former. 

The  primary  or  isolated  relative  form  of  value  of  one 
commodity  converts  some  other  commodity  into  an  isolated 
equivalent.  The  expanded  form  of  relative  value,  which  is  the 
expression  of  the  value  of  one  commodity  in  terms  of  all  other 
commodities,  endows  those  other  commodities  with  the  character 
of  particular  equivalents  differing  in  kind.  And  lastly,  a 
particular  kind  of  commodity  acquires  the  character  of 
universal  equivalent,  because  all  other  commodities  make  it  the 
material  in  which  they  uniformly  express  their  value. 

The  antagonism  between  the  relative  form  of  value  and  the 
equivalent  form,  the  two  poles  of  the  value  form,  is  developed 
concurrently  with  that  form  itself. 

The  first  form,  20  yds.  of  linen  =  one  coat,  already  contains 
this  antagonism,  without  as  yet  fixing  it.  According  as  we 
read  this  equation  forwards  or  backwards,  the  parts  played  by 
the  linen  and  the  coat  are  different.  In  the  one  case  the- 
relative  value  of  the  linen  is  expressed  in  the  coat,  in  the> 
other  case  the  relative  value  of  the  coat  is  expressed  in  the 
linen.  In  this  first  form  of  value,  therefore,  it  is  difficult  to 
grasp  the  polar  contrast. 

Form  B  shows  that  only  one  single  commodity  at  a  time  can 
completely  expand  its  relative  value,  and  that  it  acquires  this 
expanded  form  only  because,  and  in  so  far  as,  all  other  com- 
modities are,  with  respect  to  it,  equivalents.  Here  we  cannot 
reverse  the  equation,  as  we  can  the  equation  20  yds.  of  linen  = 
1  coat,  without  altering  its  general  character,  and  converting 
it  from  the  expanded  form  of  value  into  the  general  form  of 
value. 

Finally,  the  form  C  gives  to  the  world  of  commodities  a 
general  social  relative  form  of  value,  because,  and  in  so  far  as,, 
thereby  all  commodities,  with  the  exception  of  one,  are  excluded 


Commodities,  39 

from  the  equivalent  form.  A  single  commodity,  the  linen, 
appears  therefore  to  have  acquired  the  character  of  direct  ex- 
changeability with  every  other  commodity  because,  and  in  so 
far  as,  this  character  is  denied  to  every  other  commodity.^ 

The  commodity  that  figures  as  universal  equivalent,  is,  on 
the  other  hand,  excluded  from  the  relative  value  form.  If  the 
linen,  or  any  other  commodity  serving  as  universal  equivalent, 
were,  at  the  same  time,  to  share  in  the  relative  form  of  value, 
it  would  have  to  serve  as  its  own  equivalent.  We  should  then 
have  20  yds.  of  linen  =  20  yds.  of  linen ;  this  tautology  ex- 
presses neither  value,  nor  magnitude  of  value.  In  order  to 
express  the  relative  value  of  the  universal  equivalent,  we  must 
rather  reverse  the  form  C.  This  equivalent  has  no  relative 
form  of  value  in  common  with  other  commodities,  but  its  value 
is  relatively  expressed  by  a  never  ending  series  of  other  com- 
modities. Thus,  the  expanded  form  of  relative  value,  or  form 
B,  now  shows  itself  as  the  specific  form  of  relative  value  for  the 
equivalent  commodity. 

8.  Transition  from  the  General  form  of  value  to  the 
Money  form. 

The  universal  equivalent  form  is  a  form  of  value  in  general. 
It  can,  therefore,  be  assumed  by  any  commodity.  On  the 
other  hand,  if  a  commodity  be  found  to  have  assumed  the 
universal  equivalent  form  (form  C),  this  is  only  because  and 

^  It  is  by  no  means  self-evident  that  this  character  of  direct  and  universal  ex- 
changeability is,  so  to  speak,  a  polar  one,  and  as  intimately  connected  with  its  opposite 
pole,  the  absence  of  direct  exchangeability,  as  the  positive  pole  of  the  magnet  is  with 
its  negative  counterpart.  It  may  therefore  be  imagined  that  all  commodities  can 
simultaneously  have  this  character  impressed  upon  them,  just  as  it  can  be  imagined 
that  all  Catholics  can  be  popes  together.  It  is,  of  course,  highly  desirable  in  the  eyes 
of  the  petit  bourgeois,  for  whom  the  production  of  commodities  is  the  ne  plus  ultra 
of  human  freedom  and  individual  independence,  that  the  inconveniences  resulting 
from  this  character  of  commodities  not  being  directly  exchangeable,  should  be  re- 
moved. Proudhon's  socialism  is  a  working  out  of  this  Philistine  Utopia,  a  form  of 
socialism  which,  as  I  have  elsewhere  shown,  does  not  possess  even  the  merit  of  origin- 
ality. Long  before  his  time,  the  task  was  attempted  with  much  better  success  by 
Gray,  Bray,  and  others.  But,  for  all  that,  wisdom  of  this  kind  flourishes  even  now 
in  certain  circles  under  the  name  of  ** science."  Never  has  any  school  played  more 
tricks  with  the  word  science,  than  that  of  Proudhon,  for 

"  wo  Begriffe  fehlen 
Da  stellt  zur  rechten  Zeit  ein  Wort  sich  ein. " 


40  Capitalist  Production, 

in  so  far  as  it  has  been  excluded  from  the  rest  of  all  other 
commodities  as  their  equivalent,  and  that  by  their  own  act. 
And  from  the  moment  that  this  exclusion  becomes  finally 
restricted  to  one  particular  commodity,  from  that  moment  only, 
the  general  form  of  relative  value  of  the  world  of  commodities 
obtains  real  consistence  and  general  social  validity. 

The  particular  commodity,  with  whose  bodily  form  the 
equivalent  form  is  thus  socially  identified,  now  becomes  the 
money  commodity,  or  serves  as  money.  It  becomes  the  special 
social  function  of  that  commodity,  and  consequently  its  social 
monopoly,  to  play  within  the  world  of  commodities  the  part  of 
the  universal  equivalent.  Amongst  the  commodities  which,  in 
form  B,  figure  as  particular  equivalents  of  the  linen,  and,  in 
form  C,  express  in  common  their  relative  values  in  linen,  this 
foremost  place  has  been  attained  by  one  in  particular — namely, 
gold.     If,  then,  in  form  C  we  replace  the  linen  by  gold,  we  get, 

D.  The  Money  form, 

20  yards  of  linen        = 

1  coat  = 

10  K)  ot  tea  = 

40  lb  of  cofi-ee  =      V         g  ounces  of  gold 

1  qr.  of  corn  = 

J  a  ton  of  iron  = 

X  commodity  A  = 

In  passing  from  form  A  to  form  B,  and  from  the  latter  to 
form  C,  the  changes  are  fundamental.  On  the  other  hand, 
there  is  no  difference  between  forms  C  and  D,  except  that,  in 
the  latter,  gold  has  assumed  the  equivalent  form  in  the  place 
of  linen.  Gold  is  in  form  D,  what  linen  was  in  form  C — the 
universal  equivalent.  The  progress  consists  in  this  alone,  that 
the  character  of  direct  and  universal  exchangeability — in  other 
words,  that  the  universal  equivalent  form — has  now,  by  social 
custom,  become  finally  identified  with  the  substance,  gold. 

Gold  is  now  money  with  reference  to  all  other  commodities 
only  because  it  was  previously,  with  reference  to  them,  a 
simple  commodity.     Like  all   other  commodities,  it  was  also 


Commodities,  41 

capable  of  serving  as  an  equivalent,  either  as  simple  equivalent 
in  isolated  exchanges,  or  as  particular  equivalent  by  the  side 
of  others.  Gradually  it  began  to  serve,  within  varying  limits, 
as  universal  equivalent.  So  soon  as  it  monopolises  this  posi- 
tion in  the  expression  of  value  for  the  world  of  commodities, 
it  becomes  the  money  commodity,  and  then,  and  not  till  then, 
does  form  D  become  distinct  from  form  C,  and  the  general 
form  of  value  become  changed  into  the  money  form. 

The  elementary  expression  of  the  relative  value  of  a  single 
commodity,  such  as  linen,  in  terms  of  the  commodity,  such  as 
gold,  that  plays  the  part  of  money,  is  the  price  form  of  that 
commodity.     The  price  form  of  the  linen  is  therefore 

20  yards  of  linen  =  2  ounces  of  gold,  or,  if  2  ounces  of  gold 
when  coined  are  £2,  20  yards  of  linen  =  £2. 

The  difficulty  in  forming  a  concept  of  the  money  form,  con- 
sists in  clearly  comprehending  the  universal  equivalent  form, 
and  as  a  necessary  corollary,  the  general  form  of  value,  form  C. 
The  latter  is  deducible  from  form  B,  the  expanded  form  of 
value,  the  essential  component  element  of  which,  we  saw,  is 
form  A,  20  yards  of  linen  =  1  coat  or  x  commodity  A  =  y  com- 
modity B.  The  simple  commodity  form  is  therefore  the  germ 
of  the  money  form. 


Section  4. — The  fetishism  of  commodities  and  the  secret  thereof. 

A  commodity  appears,  at  first  sight,  a  very  trivial  thing,  and 
easily  understood.  Its  analysis  shows  that  it  is,  in  reality,  a 
very  queer  thing,  abounding  in  metaphysical  subtleties  and 
theological  niceties.  So  far  as  it  is  a  value  in  use,  there  is 
nothing  mysterious  about  it,  whether  we  consider  it  from  the 
point  of  view  that  by  its  properties  it  is  capable  of  satisfying 
human  wants,  or  from  the  point  that  those  properties  are  the 
product  of  human  labour.  It  is  as  clear  as  noon-day,  that  man, 
by  his  industry,  changes  the  forms  of  the  materials  furnished 
by  nature,  in  such  a  way  as  to  make  them  useful  to  him.  The 
form  of  wood,  for  instance,  is  altered,  by  making  a  table  out  of 
it.     Yet,  for  all  that,  the  table  continues  to  be  that  common, 


42  Capitalist  Prodziction, 

every-day  thing,  wood.  But,  so  soon  as  it  steps  forth  as  a 
commodity,  it  is  changed  into  something  transcendent.  It  not 
only  stands  with  its  feet  on  the  ground,  but,  in  relation  to  all 
other  commodities,  it  stands  on  its  head,  and  evolves  out  of  its 
wooden  brain  grotesque  ideas,  far  more  wonderful  than  "  table- 
turning  "  ever  was. 

The  mystical  character  of  commodities  does  not  originate, 
therefore,  in -their  use-value.  Just  as  little  does  it  proceed  from 
the  nature  of  the  determining  factors  of  value.  For,  in  the 
first  place,  however  varied  the  useful  kinds  of  labour,  or  pro- 
ductive activities,  may  be,  it  is  a  physiological  fact,  that  they 
are  functions  of  the  human  organism,  and  that  each  such  func- 
tion, whatever  may  be  its  nature  or  form,  is  essentially  the  ex- 
penditure of  human  brain,  nerves,  muscles,  &c.  Secondly,  with 
regard  to  that  which  forms  the  ground-work  for  the  quantitative 
determination  of  value,  namely,  the  duration  of  that  expendi- 
ture, or  the  quantity  of  labour,  it  is  quite  clear  that  there  is  a 
jmlpable  difference  between  its  quantity  and  quality.  In  all 
states  of  society,  the  labour-time  that  it  costs  to  produce  the 
means  of  subsistence,  must  necessarily  be  an  object  of  interest 
to  mankind,  though  not  of  equal  interest  in  different  stages  of 
development.^  And  lastly,  from  the  moment  that  men  in  any 
way  work  for  one  another,  their  labour  assumes  a  social  form. 

Whence,  then,  arises  the  enigmatical  character  of  the  product 
of  labour,  so  soon  as  it  assumes  the  form  of  commodities  ? 
Clearly  from  this  form  itself.  The  equality  of  all  sorts  of 
human  labour  is  expressed  objectively  by  their  products  all 
being  equally  values;  the  measure  of  the  expenditure  of  labour- 
T30wer  by  the  duration  of  that  expenditure,  takes  the  form  of 
the  quantity  of  value  of  the  products  of  labour;  and  finally, 
the  mutual  relations  of  the  producers,  within  which  the  social 
character  of  their  labour  affirms  itself,  take  the  form  of  a 
social  relation  between  the  products. 

A  commodity  is  therefore  a  mysterious  thing,  simply  because 
in  it  the  social  character  of  men's  labour  appears  to  them  as  an 

1  Among  the  ancient  Germans  the  unit  for  measuring  land  was  what  could  be 
harvested  in  a  day,  and  was  called  Tagwerk,  Tagwanne  (jurnale,  or  terra  jurnalis,  or 
diornalis),  Mannsmaad,  &c.  (See  G.  L.  von  Maurer  Einleitung  zur  Geschichte  dei; 
Mark—,  &c.  Verfassung,  Miinchen,  1859,  p.  129-59.) 


Commodities.  43 

objective  character  stamped  upon  the  product  o£  that  labour;, 
because  the  relation  of  the  producers  to  the  sum  total  of  their 
own  labour  is  presented  to  them  as  a  social  relation,  existing- 
not  between  themselves,  but  between  the  products  of  their 
labour.  This  is  the  reason  why  the  products  of  labour  become 
commodities,  social  things  whose  qualities  are  at  the  same  time 
perceptible  and  imperceptible  by  the  senses.  In  the  same  way 
the  light  from  an  object  is  perceived  by  us  not  as  the  subjective 
excitation  of  our  optic  nerve,  but  as  the  objective  form  of 
something  outside  the  eye  itself.  But,  in  the  act  of  seeing^ 
there  is  at  all  events,  an  actual  passage  of  light  from  one  thing 
to  another,  from  the  external  object  to  the  eye.  There  is  a 
physical  relation  between  physical  things.  But  it  is  different 
with  commodities.  There,  the  existence  of  the  things  qua 
commodities,  and  the  value  relation  between  the  products  of 
labour  which  stamps  them  as  commodities,  have  absolutely  no 
connection  with  their  physical  properties  and  with  the  material 
relations  arising  therefrom.  There  it  is  a  definite  social  rela- 
tion between  men,  that  assumes,  in  their  eyes,  the  fantastic 
form  of  a  relation  between  things.  In  order,  therefore,  to  find: 
an  analogy,  we  must  have  recourse  to  the  mist-enveloped  regions 
of  the  religious  world.  In  that  world  the  productions  of  the 
human  brain  appear  as  independent  beings  endowed  with  life,, 
and  entering  into  relation  both  with  one  another  and  the  human 
race.  So  it  is  in  the  world  of  commodities  with  the  products 
of  men's  hands.  This  I  call  the  Fetishism  which  attaches  itself 
to  the  products  of  labour,  so  soon  as  they  are  produced  as  com- 
modities, and  which  is  therefore  inseparable  from  the  produc- 
tion of  commodities. 

This  Fetishism  of  commodities  has  its  origin,  as  the  fore- 
going analysis  has  already  shown,  in  the  peculiar  social' 
character  of  the  labour  that  produces  them. 

As  a  general  rule,  articles  of  utility  become  commodities,  only 
because  they  are  products  of  the  labour  of  private  individuals 
or  groups  of  individuals  who  carry  on  their  work  independently 
of  each  other.  The  sum  total  of  the  labour  of  all  these  private 
individuals  forms  the  aggregate  labour  of  society.  Since  the 
producers  do  not  come  into  social  contact  with  each  other  until 


44  Capitalist  Production, 

they  exchange  their  products,  the  specific  social  character  of 
each  producer's  labour  does  not  show  itself  except  in  the  act  of 
exchange.  In  other  words,  the  labour  of  the  individual  asserts 
itself  as  a  part  of  the  labour  of  society,  only  by  means  of  the 
relations  which  tbe  act  of  exchange  establishes  directly  between 
the  products,  and  indirectly,  through  them,  between  the  pro- 
ducers. To  the  latter,  therefore,  the  relations  connecting  the 
labour  of  one  individual  with  that  of  the  rest  appear,  not  as 
direct  social  relations  between  individuals  at  work,  but  as  what 
they  reallj^  are,  material  relations  between  persons  and  social 
relations  between  things.  It  is  only  by  being  exchanged  that 
the  products  of  labour  acquire,  as  values,  one  uniform  social 
status,  distinct  from  their  varied  forms  of  existence  as  objects 
of  utility.  This  division  of  a  product  into  a  useful  thing  and 
a  value  becomes  practically  important,  only  when  exchange 
has  acquired  such  an  extension  that  useful  articles  are  produced 
for  the  purpose  of  being  exchanged,  and  their  character  as 
values  has  therefore  to  be  taken  into  account,  beforehand, 
during  production.  From  this  moment  the  labour  of  the 
individual  producer  acquires  socially  a  two-fold  character.  On 
the  one  hand,  it  must,  as  a  definite  useful  kind  of  labour, 
satisfy  a  definite  social  want,  and  thus  hold  its  place  as  part 
and  parcel  of  the  collective  labour  of  all,  as  a  branch  of  a  social 
division  of  labour  that  has  sprung  up  spontaneously.  On  the 
other  hand,  it  can  satisfy  the  manifold  wants  of  the  individual 
producer  himself,  only  in  so  far  as  the  mutual  exchangeability 
of  all  kinds  of  useful  private  labour  is  an  established  social  fact, 
and  therefore  the  private  useful  labour  of  each  producer  ranks 
on  an  equality  with  that  of  all  others.  The  equalisation  of  the 
most  different  kinds  of  labour  can  be  the  result  only  of  an 
abstraction  from  their  inequalities,  or  of  reducing  them  to 
their  common  denominator,  viz.,  expenditure  of  human  labour  \ 
power  or  human  labour  in  the  abstract.  The  two-fold  social 
•character  of  the  labour  of  the  individual  appears  to  him,  when 
Teflected  in  his  brain,  only  under  those  forms  which  are  im- 
pressed upon  that  labour  in  everyday  practice  by  the  exchange 
of  products.  In  this  way,  the  character  that  his  own  labour 
possesses  of  being  socially  useful  takes  the  form  of  the  condition, 


Commodities.  45 

that  the  product  must  be  not  only  useful,  but  useful  for  others, 
and  the  social  character  that  his  particular  labour  has  of  being 
the  equal  of  all  other  particular  kinds  of  labour,  takes  the  form 
that  all  the  physically  different  articles  that  are  the  products 
of  labour,  have  one  common  quality,  viz.,  that  of  having  value. 
Hence,  when  we  bring  the  products  of  our  labour  into  rela- 

^  tion  with  each  other  as  values,  it  is  not  because  we  see  in  these 
articles  the  material  receptacles  of  homogeneous  human  labour. 
Quite  the  contrary :  whenever,  by  an  exchange,  we  equate  as 
values  our  different  products,  by  that  very  act,  we  also  equate, 
as  human  labour,  the  different  kinds  of  labour  expended  upon 
them.  We  are  not  aware  of  this,  nevertheless  we  do  it.^ 
Value,  therefore,  does  not  stalk  about  with  a  label  describing 
what  it  is.  It  is  value,  rather,  that  converts  every  product 
into  a  social  hieroglyphic.  Later  on,  we  try  to  decipher  the 
hieroglyphic,  to  get  behind  the  secret  of  our  own  social  pro- 
ducts ;  for  to  stamp  an  object  of  utility  as  a  value,  is  just  as 
much  a  social  product  as  language.  The  recent  scientific  dis- 
covery, that  the  products  of  labour,  so  far  as  they  are  values, 

\  are  but  material  expressions  of  the  human  labour  spent  in 
their  production,  marks,  indeed,  an  epoch  in  the  history  of  the 
development  of  the  human  race,  but,  by  no  means,  dissipates 
the  mist  through  which  the  social  character  of  labour  appears 
to  us  to  be  an  objective  character  of  the  products  themselves. 
The  fact,  that  in  the  particular  form  of  production  with  which 
we  are  dealing,  viz.,  the  production  of  commodities,  the  specific 
social  character  of  private  labour  carried  on  independently, 
consists  in  the  equality  of  every  kind  of  that  labour,  by  virtue 
of  its  being  human  labour,  which  character,  therefore,  assumes 
in  the  product  the  form  of  value — this  fact  appears  to  the 
producers,  notwithstanding  the  discovery  above  referred  to, 
to  be  just  as  real  and  final,  as  the  fact,  that,  after  the  discovery 
by  science  of  the  component  gases  of  air,  the  atmosphere  itself 

J  remained  unaltered. 
What,  first  of  all,  practically  concerns  producers  when  the}^ 

1  When,  therefore,  Galiani  says:  Value  is  a  relation  between  persons — "La 
Ricchezza  e  una  ragione  tra  due  persone," — he  ought  to  have  added  :  a  relation  be- 
tween persons  expressed  as  a  relation  between  things.  (Galiani :  Delia  Moneta,  p. 
221,  V.  III.  of  Custodi's  collection  of  "  Scrittori  Classici  Italiani  di  Economia  Poli- 
tica."    Parte  Moderna,  Milano,  1803) 


46  Capitalist  Prodtcction. 

make  an  exchan|:^e,  is  the  question,  how  much  of  some  other 
product  they  get  for  their  own?  in  what  proportions  the  pro- 
ducts are  exchangeable  ?  When  these  proportions  have,  by 
-custom,  attained  a  certain  stability,  they  appear  to  result  from 
the  nature  of  the  products,  so  that,  for  instance,  one  ton  of  iron 
and  two  ounces  of  gold  appear  as  naturally  to  be  of  equal  value 
as  a  pound  of  gold  and  a  pound  of  iron  in  spite  of  their 
different  physical  and  chemical  qualities  appear  to  be  of  equal 
Aveight.  The  character  of  having  value,  when  once  impressed 
upon  products,  obtains  fixity  only  by  reason  of  their  acting  and 
re-acting  upon  each  other  as  quantities  of  value.  These 
quantities  vary  continually,  independently  of  the  will,  fore- 
sight and  action  of  the  producers.  To  them,  their  own  social 
action  takes  the  form  of  the  action  of  objects,  which  rule  the 
producers  instead  of  being  ruled  by  them.  It  requires  a  fully 
developed  production  of  commodities  before,  from  accumulated 
•experience  alone,  the  scientific  conviction  springs  up,  that  all 
the  different  kinds  of  private  labour,  which  are  carried  on  in- 
dependently of  each  other,  and  yet  as  spontaneously  de^veloped 
branches  of  the  social  division  of  labour,  are  continually  being 
reduced  to  the  quantitative  proportions  in  which  society  re- 
quires them.  And  why  ?  Because,  in  the  midst  of  all  the 
accidental  and  ever  fluctuating  exchange-relations  between 
the  products,  the  labour-time  socially  necessary  for  their  pro- 
duction forcibly  asserts  itself  like  an  over-riding  law  of  nature. 
The  law  of  gravity  thus  asserts  itself  when  a  house  falls  about 
our  ears.^  The  determination  of  the  magnitude  of  value  b^^ 
labour-time  is  therefore  a  secret,  hidden  under  the  apparent 
fluctuations  in  the  relative  values  of  commodities.  Its  dis- 
covery, while  removing  all  appearance  of  mere  accidentality 
from  the  determination  of  the  magnitude  of  the  values  of 
products,  yet  in  no  way  alters  the  mode  in  which  that 
determination  takes  place. 

Man's  reflections  on  the  forms  of  social  life,  and  consequently, 

1  "What  are  we  to  think  of  a  law  that  asserts  itself  only  by  periodical  revolu- 
tions? It  is  just  nothing  but  a  law  of  Nature,  founded  on  the  want  of  knowledge  of 
those  whose  action  is  the  subject  of  it."  (Friedrich  Engels  :  Umrisse  zu  einer  Kritik 
der  Nation 4okonomie,"  in  the  "  Deutsch-franzosische  Jahrblicher,"  edited  by  Arnold 
Ruge  and  Karl  Marx.     Paris,  1844.) 


Commodities. 


47 


also,  his  scientific  analysis  of  those  forms,  take  a  course  directly 
opposite  to  that  of  their  actual  historical  development.  He 
begins,  post  festum,  with  the  results  of  the  process  of  develop- 
ment ready  to  hand  before  him.  The  characters  that  stamp 
products  as  commodities,  and  whose  establishment  is  a  necessary 
preliminary  to  the  circulation  of  commodities,  have  already 
acquired  the  stability  of  natural,  self-understood  forms  of  social 
life,  before  man  seeks  to  decipher,  not  their  historical  character, 
for  in  his  eyes  they  are  immutable,  but  their  meaning. 
Consequently  it  was  the  analysis  of  the  prices  of  commodities 
that  alone  led  to  the  determination  of  the  magnitude  of  value, 
and  it  was  the  common  expression  of  all  commodities  in  money 
that  alone  led  to  the  establishment  of  their  characters  as  values. 
It  is,  however,  just  this  ultimate  money  form  of  the  world  of 
€ommodities  that  actually  conceals,  instead  of  disclosing,  the 
social  character  of  piivate  labour,  and  the  social  relations 
between  the  individual  producers.  When  I  state  that  coats  or 
boots  stand  in  a  relation  to  linen,  because  it  is  the  universal 
incarnation  of  abstract  human  labour,  the  absurdity  of  the 
statement  is  self-evident.  Nevertheless,  when  the  producers  of 
coats  and  boots  compare  those  articles  with  linen,  or,  what  is 
the  same  thing,  with  gold  or  silver,  as  the  universal  equivalent, 
they  express  the  relation  between  their  own  private  labour  and 
the  collective  labour  of  society  in  the  same  absurd  form. 

The  categories  of  bourgeois  economy  consist  of  such  like 
forms.  They  are  forms  of  thought  expressing  with  social 
validity  the  conditions  and  relations  of  a  definite,  historically 
determined  mode  of  production,  viz.,  the  production  of  com- 
modities. The  whole  mystery  of  commodities,  all  the  magic 
and  necromancy  that  surrounds  the  products  of  labour  as  long- 
as  they  take  the  form  of  commodities,  vanishes  therefore,  so 
soon  as  we  come  to  other  forms  of  production. 

Since  Robinson  Crusoe's  experiences  are  a  favourite  theme 
with  political  economists,^  let  us  take  a  look  at  him  on  his 

1  Even  Rjcardo  has  his  stories  k  la  Robinson.  "  He  makes  the  primitive  hunter  and 
the  primitive  fisher  straightway,  as  owners  of  commodities,  exchange  fish  and  game  in 
the  proportion  in  which  labour-time  is  incorporated  in  these  exchange  values.  On 
this  occasion  he  commits  the  anachronism  of  making  these  men  apply  to  the  calcula- 
tion, so  far  as  their  implements  have  to  be  taken  into  account,  the  annuity  tables  in 


48  Capitalist  Production. 

island.  Moderate  though  he  be,  yet  some  few  wants  he  has  to 
satisfy,  and  must  therefore  do  a  little  useful  work  of  various 
sorts,  such  as  making  tools  and  furniture,  taming  goats,  fishing 
and  hunting.  Of  his  prayers  and  the  like  we  take  no  account, 
since  they  are  a  source  of  pleasure  to  him,  and  he  looks  upon 
them  as  so  much  recreation.  In  spite  of  the  variety  of  hia 
work,  he  knows  that  his  labour,  whatever  its  form,  is  but  the 
activity  of  one  and  the  same  Robinson,  and  consequently,  that 
it  consists  of  nothing  but  different  modes  of  human  labour. 
Necessity  itself  compels  him  to  apportion  his  time  accurately 
between  his  different  kinds  of  work.  Whether  one  kind 
occupies  a  greater  space  in  his  general  activity  than  another, 
depends  on  the  difficulties,  greater  or  less  as  the  case  may  be, 
to  be  overcome  in  attaining  the  useful  effect  aimed  at.  This 
our  friend  Eobinson  soon  learns  by  experience,  and  having 
rescued  a  watch,  ledger,  and  pen  and  ink  from  the  wreck, 
commences,  like  a  true-born  Briton,  to  keep  a  set  of  books. 
His  stock-book  contains  a  list  of  the  objects  of  utility  that 
belong  to  him,  of  the  operations  necessary  for  their  production  • 
and  lastly,  of  the  labour  time  that  definite  quantities  of  those 
objects  have,  on  an  average,  cost  him.  All  the  relations 
between  Robinson  and  the  objects  that  form  this  wealth  of  his 
own  creation,  are  here  so  simple  and  clear  as  to  be  intelligible 
without  exertion,  even  to  Mr.  Sedley  Taylor.  And  yet  those 
relations  contain  all  that  is  essential  to  the  determination  of 
value. 

Let  us  now  transport  ourselves  from  Robinson's  island 
bathed  in  light  to  the  European  middle  ages  shrouded  in  dark- 
ness. Here,  instead  of  the  independent  man,  we  find  everyone 
dependent,  serfs  and  lords,  vassals  and  suzerains,  laymen  and 
clergy.  Personal  dependence  here  characterises  the  social 
relations  of  production  just  as  much  as  it  does  the  other  spheres 
of  life  organized  on  the  basis  of  that  production.  But  for  the 
very  reason  that  personal  dependence  forms  the  groundwork 
of  society,  there  is  no  necessity  for  labour  and  its  products  to 

current  use  on  the  London  Exchange  in  the  year  1817.  *  The  parallelograms  of  Mr. 
Owen '  appear  to  be  the  only  form  of  society,  besides  the  bourgeois  form,  with  which 
he  was  acquainted."    (Karl  Marx  :  "Zur  Kritik,"  &c.,  p.  38,  39.) 


Commodities.  49 

assume  a  fantastic  form  different  from  tlieir  reality.  They 
take  the  shape,  in  the  transactions  of  society,  of  services  in  kind 
and  payments  in  kind.  Here  the  particular  and  natural  form 
of  labour,  and  not,  as  in  a  society  based  on  production  of  com- 
modities, its  general  abstract  form  is  the  immediate  social  form 
of  labour.  Compulsory  labour  is  just  as  properly  measured  by 
time,  as  commodity -producing  labour;  but  every  serf  knows 
that  what  he  expends  in  the  service  of  his  lord,  is  a  definite 
quantit}^  of  his  own  personal  labour-power.  The  tithe  to  be 
rendcxed  to  the  priest  is  more  matter  of  fact  than  his  blessing. 
No  matter,  then,  what  we  may  think  of  the  parts  played  by  the 
different  classes  of  people  themseWes  in  this  society;  the  social 
relations  between  individuals  in  the  performance  of  their 
labour,  appear  at  all  events  as  their  own  mutual  personal  rela- 
tions, and  are  not  disguised  under  the  shape  of  social  relations 
between  the  products  of  labour. 

For  an  example  of  labour  in  common  or  directly  associated 
labour,  we  have  no  occasion  to  go  back  to  that  spontaneously 
developed  form  which  we  find  on  the  threshold  of  the  history 
of  all  civilized  races.^  We  have  one  close  at  hand  in  the 
patriarchal  industries  of  a  peasant  family,  that  produces  corn, 
cattle,  yarn,  linen,  and  clothing  for  home  use.  These  different 
articles  are,  as  regards  the  family,  so  many  products  of  its 
labour,  but  as  between  themselves,  they  are  not  commodities. 
The  different  kinds  of  labour,  such  as  tillage,  cattle  tending, 
spinning,  weaving  and  making  clothes,  which  result  in  the 
various  products,  are  in  themselves,  and  such  as  they  are,  direct 
social  functions,  because  functions  of  the  family,  which,  just  as 
much  as  a  society  based  on  the  production  of  commodities, 
possesses  a  spontaneously  developed  system  of  division  of 
labour.     The  distribution  of  the  work  within  the  family,  and 

■^  "A  ridiculous  presumption  has  latterly  got  abroad  that  common  j)roperty  in  its 
primitive  form  is  specifically  a  Slavonian,  or  even  exclusively  Russian  form.  It  is  the 
primitive  form  that  we  can  prove  to  have  existed  amongst  Romans,  Teutons,  and 
Celts,  and  even  to  this  day  we  find  numerous  examples,  ruins  though  they  be,  in 
India.  A  more  exhaustive  study  of  Asiatic,  and  especially  of  Indian  forms  of  common 
property,  would  show  how  from  the  different  forms  of  primitive  common  property, 
different  forms  of  its  dissolution  have  been  developed.  Thus,  for  instance,  the  various 
original  types  of  Roman  and  Teutonic  private  property  are  deducible  from  different 
forms  of  Indian  common  property."    (Karl  Marx.  "  Zur  Kritik,"  &c.,  p.  10.) 

D 


50  Capitalist  Production. 

the  regulation  of  the  labour- time  of  the  several  members, 
depend  as  well  upon  differences  of  age  and  sex  as  upon  natural 
conditions  varying  with  the  seasons.  The  labour-power  of  each 
individual,  by  its  very  nature,  operates  in  this  case  merely  as 
a  definite  portion  of  the  whole  labour-power  of  the  family,  and 
therefore,  the  measure  of  the  expenditure  of  individual  labour- 
power  by  its  duration,  appears  here  by  its  very  nature  as  a 
social  character  of  their  labour. 

Let  us  now  picture  to  ourselves,  by  way  of  change,  a  com- 
munity of  free  individuals,  carrying  on  their  work  with  the 
means  of  production  in  common,  in  which  the  labour-power  of 
all  the  different  individuals  is  consciously  applied  as  the 
combined  labour-power  of  the  community.  All  the  charac- 
teristics of  Robinson's  labour  are  here  repeated,  but  with  this 
difference,  that  they  are  social,  instead  of  individual.  Every- 
thing produced  by  him  was  exclusively  the  result  of  his  own 
personal  labour,  and  therefore  simply  an  object  of  use  for 
himself  The  total  product  of  our  community  is  a  social 
product.  One  portion  serves  as  fresh  means  of  production  and 
remains  social.  But  another  portion  is  consumed  by  the 
members  as  means  of  subsistence.  A  distribution  of  this 
portion  amongst  them  is  consequently  necessary.  The  mode 
of  this  distribution  will  vary  with  the  productive  organization 
of  the  community,  and  the  degree  of  historical  development 
attained  by  the  producers.  We  will  assume,  but  merely  for 
the  sake  of  a  parallel  with  the  production  of  commodities,  that 
the  share  of  each  individual  producer  in  the  means  of  subsis- 
tence is  determined  by  his  labour-time.  Labour-time  would, 
in  that  case,  play  a  double  part.  Its  apportionment  in  accor- 
dance with  a  definite  social  plan  maintains  the  proper  proportion 
between  the  different  kinds  of  work  to  be  done  and  the  various 
wants  of  the  community.  On  the  other  hand,  it  also  serves  as 
a  measure  of  the  portion  of  the  common  labour  borne  by  each 
individual,  and  of  his  share  in  the  part  of  the  total  product  des- 
tined for  individual  consumption.  The  social  relations  of  the 
individual  producers,  with  regard  both  to  their  labour  and  to  its 
products,  are  in  this  case  perfectly  simple  and  intelligible,  and 
that  with  regard  not  only  to  production  but  also  to  distribution. 


Commodities.  5 1 

The  reliofious  world  is  but  the  reflex  of  the  real  world.  i.nd 
for  a  society  based  upon  the  production  of  commodities,  in 
which  the  producers  in  general  enter  into  social  relations  with 
one  another  by  treating  their  products  as  commodities  and 
values,  whereby  they  reduce  their  individual  private  labour  to 
the  standard  of  homogeneous  human  labour — for  such  a  society, 
(Christianity  with  its  cultus  of  abstract  man,  more  especially  in 
its  bourgeois  developments,  Protestantism,  Deism,  &;c.,  is  the 
most  fitting  form  of  religion.  In  the  ancient  Asiatic  and  other 
ancient  modes  of  production,  we  find  that  the  conversion  of 
products  into  commodities,  and  therefore  the  conversion  of  men 
into  producers  of  commodities,  holds  a  subordinate  place,  which, 
however,  increases  in  importance  as  the  primitive  communities 
approach  nearer  and  nearer  to  their  dissolution.  Trading- 
nations,  properly  so  called,  exist  in  the  ancient  world  only  in 
its  interstices,  like  the  gods  of  Epicurus  in  the  Intermundia,  or 
like  Jews  in  the  pores  of  Polish  society.  Those  ancient  social 
organisms  of  production  are,  as  compared  with  bourgeois 
society,  extremely  simple  and  transparent.  But  they  are 
founded  either  on  the  immature  development  of  man  in- 
dividually, who  has  not  yet  severed  the  umbilical  cord  that 
unites  him  with  his  fellow  men  in  a  primitive  tribal  com- 
munity, or  upon  direct  relations  of  subjection.  They  can 
arise  and  exist  only  when  the  development  of  the  productive 
power  of  labour  has  not  risen  beyond  a  low  stage,  and  when, 
therefore,  the  social  relations  within  the  sphere  of  material 
life,  between  man  and  man,  and  between  man  and  Nature,  are 
correspondingly  narrow.  This  narrowness  is  reflected  in  the 
ancient  worship  of  Nature,  and  in  the  other  elements  of  the 
popular  religions.  The  religious  reflex  of  the  real  world  can, 
in  any  case,  only  then  finally  vanish,  when  the  practical  re- 
lations of  everyday  life  ofler  to  man  none  but  perfectly  in- 
telligible and  reasonable  relations  with  regard  to  his  fellowmen 
and  to  nature. 

The  life-process  of  society,  which  is  based  on  the  process  of 
material  production,  does  not  strip  off"  its  mystical  veil  until  it 
is  treated  as  production  by  freely  associated  men,  and  is  con- 
sciously regulated  by  them  in  accordance  with  a  settled  plan. 


52  Capitalist  Pivduction. 

This,  however,  demands  for  society  a  certain  material  ground- 
work or  set  of  conditions  of  existence  which  in  their  turn  are 
the  spontaneous  product  of  a  long  and  painful  process  of 
development. 

Political  economy  has  indeed  analysed,  however  incom- 
pletely, '  value  and  its  magnitude,  and  has  discovered  what  lies 
beneath  these  forms.  But  it  has  never  once  asked  the  question 
why  labour  is  represented  by  the  value  of  its  product  and  labour 
time  by  the  magnitude  of  that  value.^     These  formulae,  which 

1  The  insufficiency  of  Ricardo's  analysis  of  the  magnitude  of  value,  and  his  analysis 
is  by  far  the  best,  will  appear  from  the  3rd  and  4th  books  of  this  work.  As  regards 
value  in  general,  it  is  the  weak  point  of  the  classical  school  of  political  economy  that 
it  nowhere,  expressly  and  with  full  consciousness,  distinguishes  between  labour,  as  it 
appears  in  the  value  of  a  product  and  the  same  labour,  as  it  appears  in  the  use- 
value  of  that  product.  Of  course  the  distinction  is  practically  made,  since  this  school 
treats  labour,  at  one  time  under  its  quantitative  aspect,  at  another  under  its  qualita- 
tive aspect.  But  it  has  not  the  least  idea,  that  when  the  difference  between  various 
kinds  of  labour  is  treated  as  purely  quantitative,  their  qualitative  unity  or  equality, 
and  therefore  their  reduction  to  abstract  human  labour,  is  imj^lied.  For  instance, 
Ricardo  declares  that  he  agrees  with  Destutt  de  Tracy  in  this  proposition  :  "As  it  is 
certain  that  our  physical  and  moral  faculties  are  alone  our  original  riches,  the  em- 
ployment of  those  faculties,  labour  of  some  kind,  is  our  only  original  treasure,  audit  is 
always  from  this  employment  that  all  those  things  are  created,  which  we  call  riches. 
.  .  .  It  is  certain,  too,  that  all  those  things  only  represent  the  labour  which  has 
created  them,  and  if  they  have  a  value,  or  even  two  distinct  values,  they  can  only 
derive  them  from  that  (the  value)  of  the  labour  from  which  they  emanate. "  (Kicardo, 
The  Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.  3  Ed.  Lond.  1821,  p.  334).  We  would  here  only  point 
out,  that  Kicardo  puts  his  own  more  profound  interpretation  upon  the  words  of  Des- 
tutt. What  the  latter  really  says  is,  that  on  the  one  hand  all  things  which  constitute 
wealth  represent  the  labour  that  creates  them,  but  that  on  the  other  hand,  they  ac- 
quire their  "  two  different  values  "  (use-value  and  exchange-value)  from  "the  value 
of  labour."  He  thus  falls  into  the  commonplace  error  of  the  vulgar  economists,  who 
assume  the  value  of  one  commodity  (in  this  case  labour)  in  order  to  determine  the 
values  of  the  rest.  But  Kicardo  reads  him  as  if  he  had  said,  that  labour  (not  the 
value  of  labour)  is  embodied  both  in  use-value  and  exchange-value.  Nevertheless, 
Kicardo  himself  pays  so  little  attention  to  the  two-fold  character  of  the  labour  which 
has  a  two-fold  embodiment,  that  he  devotes  the  whole  of  his  chapter  on  "  Value  and 
Kiches,  Their  Distinctive  Properties,"  to  a  laborious  examination  of  the  trivialities 
of  a  J.  B.  Say.  And  at  the  finish  he  is  quite  astonished  to  find  that  Destutt  on  the 
one  hand  agrees  with  him  as  to  labour  being  the  source  of  value,  and  on  the  other 
hand  with  J.  B.  Say  as  to  the  notion  of  value. 

2  It  is  one  of  the  chief  failings  of  classical  economy  that  it  has  never  succeeded,  by 
means  of  its  analysis  of  commodities,  and,  in  particular,  of  their  value,  in  discover- 
ing that  form  under  which  value  becomes  exchange-value.  Even  Adam  Smith  and 
Kicardo,  the  best  representatives  of  the  school,  treat  the  form  of  value  as  a  thing  of 
no  importance,  as  having  no  connection  with  the  inherent  nature  of  commodities. 
The  reason  for  this  is  not  solely  because  their  attention  is  entirely  absorbed  in  the 
analysis  of  the  magnitude  of  value.     It  lies  deeper.     The  value  form  of  the  product 


Commodities.  5  3 

bear  stamped  upon  them  in  unmistakeable  letters,  that  they 
belong  to  a  state  of  society,  in  which  the  process  of  production 
has  the  mastery  over  man,  instead  of  being  controlled  by  him, 
such  formulae  appear  to  the  bourgeois  intellect  to  be  as  much  a 
self-evident  necessity  imposed  by  nature  as  productive  labour 
itself.  Hence  forms  of  social  production  that  preceded  the 
bourgeois  form,  are  treated  by  the  bourgeoisie  in  much  the 
same  way  as  the  Fathers  of  the  Church  treated  pre-Christian 
religions.^ 

of  labour  is  not  only  the  most  abstract,  but  is  also  the  most  universal  form,  taken  by 
the  product  in  bourgeois  production,  and  stamps  that  production  as  a  particular 
species  of  social  production,  and  thereby  gives  it  its  special  historical  character.  If 
then  we  treat  this  mode  of  production  as  one  eternally  fixed  by  nature  for  every 
state  of  society,  we  necessarily  overlook  that  which  is  the  differentia  specifica  of  the 
value-form,  and  consequently*  of  the  commodity-form,  and  of  its  further  develop- 
ments, money-form,  capital-form,  &c.  We  consequently  find  that  economists,  who 
are  thoroughly  agreed  as  to  labour  time  being  the  measure  of  the  magnitude  of  value, 
have  the  most  strange  and  contradictory  ideas  of  money,  the  perfected  form  of  the 
general  equivalent.  This  is  seen  in  a  striking  manner  when  they  treat  of  banking, 
where  the  commonplace  definitions  of  money  will  no  longer  hold  water.  This  led  to 
the  rise  of  a  restored  mercantile  system  (Ganilh,  &c.),  which  sees  in  value  nothing 
but  a  social  form,  or  rather  the  unsubstantial  ghost  of  that  form.  Once  for  all  I  may 
here  state,  that  by  classical  political  economy,  I  understand  that  economy  which, 
since  the  time  of  W.  Petty,  has  investigated  the  real  relations  of  production  in  bour- 
geois society,  in  contradistinction  to  vulgar  economy,  which  deals  with  appearances 
only,  ruminates  without  ceasing  on  the  materials  long  since  provided  by  scientific 
economy,  and  there  seeks  plausible  explanations  of  the  most  obtrusive  phenomena, 
for  bourgeois  daily  use,  but  for  the  rest,  confines  itself  to  systematizing  in  a  pedantic 
way,  and  proclaiming  for  everlasting  truths,  the  trite  ideas  held  by  the  self -compla- 
cent bourgeoisie  with  regard  to  their  own  world,  to  them  the  best  of  all  possible 
worlds. 

1  ' '  Les  economistes  ont  une  singuliere  maniere  de  proceder.  II  n'y  a  pour  eux  que 
deux  sortes  d'institutions,  celles  de  I'art  et  celles  de  la  nature.  Les  institutions  de 
la  feodalite  sont  des  institutions  artificielles,  celles  de  la  bourgeoisie  sont  des  institu- 
tions naturelles.  lis  ressemblent  en  ceci  aux  theologiens,  qui  eux  aussi  etablissent 
deux  sortes  de  religions.  Toute  religion  qui  n'est  pas  la  leur,  est  une  invention  des 
hommes,  tandis  que  leur  propre  religion  est  une  emanation  de  Dieu — Ainsi  il 
y  a  eu  de  I'histoire,  mais  il  n'y  en  a  plus."  (Karl  Marx.  Misere  de  la  Philosophic. 
Reponse  a  la  Philosophie  de  la  Misere  par  M.  Proudhon,  1847  p.  113.)  Truly  comical 
is  M.  Bastiat,  who  imagines  that  the  ancient  Greeks  and  Romans  lived  by  plunder 
alone.  But  when  people  plunder  for  centuries,  there  must  always  be  something  at 
hand  for  them  to  seize ;  the  objects  of  plunder  must  be  continually  reproduced.  It 
would  thus  appear  that  even  Greeks  and  Romans  had  some  process  of  production, 
consequently,  an  economy,  which  just  as  much  constituted  the  material  basis  of  their 
world,  as  bourgeois  economy  constitutes  that  of  our  modern  world.  Or  perhaps  Bas- 
tiat means,  that  a  mode  of  production  based  on  slavery  is  based  on  a  system  of  plun- 
der. In  that  case  he  treads  on  dangerous  ground.  If  a  giant  thinker  like  Aristotle 
erred  in  his  appreciation  of  slave  labour,  why  should  a  dwarf  economist  like  Bastiat 
be  right  in  his  appreciation  of  wage  labour  ?— I  seize  this  opportunity  of  shortly 


54  Capitalist  Production, 

'  To  what  extent  some  economists  are  misled  by  the  Fetishism 
inherent  in  commodities,  or  by  the  objective  appearance  of  the 
social  characteristics  of  labour,  is  shown,  amongst  other  ways, 
by  the  dull  and  tedious  quarrel  over  the  part  played  by  Nature 
in  the  formation  of  exchange  value.  Since  exchange  value  is 
a  definite  social  manner  of  expressing  the  amount  of  labour 
bestowed  upon  an  object,  Nature  has  no  more  to  do  with  it, 
than  it  has  in  fixing  the  course  oi  exchange. 

The  mode  of  pioduction  in  which  the  product  takes  the 
form  of  a  commodity,  or  is  produced  directly  for  exchange,  is  the 
most  general  and  most  embryonic  form  of  bourgeois  production. 
It  therefore  makes  its  appearance  at  an  early  date  in  history, 
though  not  in  the  same  predominating  and  characteristic 
manner  as  now-a-days.  Hence  its  Fetish  character  is  com- 
paratively easy  to  be  seen  through.  But  when  we  come 
to  more  concrete  forms,  even  this  appearance  of  simplicity 
vanishes.  Whence  arose  the  illusions  of  the  monetary  system  ? 
To  it  gold  and  silver,  when  serving  as  money,  did  not  repre- 
sent a  social  relation  between  producers,  but  were  natural 
objects  with  strange  social  properties.  And  modern  economy, 
which  looks  down  with  such  disdain  on  the  monetary  system, 
does  not  its  superstition  come  out  as  clear  as  noon-day,  when- 
ever it  treats  of  capital  ?  How  long  is  it  since  economy  dis- 
carded the  physiocratic  illusion,  that  rents  grow  out  of  the 
soil  and  not  out  of  society  ? 

answering  an  objection  taken  by  a  German  paper  in  America,  to  my  work,  "  Zur 
Kritik  der  Pol.  Oekonomie,  1859."  In  the  estimation  of  that  paper,  my  view  that]each 
special  mode  of  production  and  the  social  relations  corresponding  to  it,  in  short,  that 
the  economic  structure  of  society,  is  the  real  basis  on  which  the  juridical  and  political 
superstructure  is  raised,  and  to  which  definite  social  forms  of  thought  correspond ; 
that  the  mode  of  production  determines  the  character  of  the  social,  political,  and  in- 
tellectual life  generally,  all  this  is  very  true  for  our  own  times,  in  which  material 
interests  preponderate,  but  not  for  the  middle  ages,  in  which  Catholicism,  nor  for 
Athens  and  Rome,  where  politics,  reigned  supreme.  In  the  first  place  it  strikes  one 
as  an  odd  thing  for  any  one  to  suppose  that  these  well-worn  phrases  about  the  middle 
ages  and  the  ancient  world  are  unknown  to  anyone  else.  This  much,  however,  is 
clear,  that  the  middle  ages  could  not  live  on  Catholicism,  nor  the  ancient  world  on 
politics.  On  the  contrary,  it  is  the  mode  in  which  they  gained  a  livelihood  that  ex- 
plains why  here  politics,  and  there  Catholicism,  played  the  chief  part.  For  the  rest, 
it  requires  but  a  slight  acquaintance  with  the  history  of  the  Koman  republic,  for 
example,  to  be  aware  that  its  secret  history,  is  the  history  of  its  landed  projjerty. 
On  the  other  hand,  Don  Quixote  long  ago  paid  the  penalty  for  wrongly  imagining 
that  knight  errantry  was  compatible  with  all  economical  forms  of  society. 


Commodities.  55 

But  not  to  anticipate,  we  will  content  ourselves  with  yet 
another  example  relating  to  the  commodity  form.  Could  com- 
modities themselves  speak,  they  would  say:  Our  use- value  may 
be  a  thing  that  interests  men.  It  is  no  part  of  us  as  objects. 
What,  however,  does  belong  to  us  as  objects,  is  our  value.  Our 
natural  intercourse  as  commodities  proves  it.  In  the  eyes  of 
each  other  we  are  nothing  but  exchange  values.  Now  listen 
how  those  commodities  speak  through  the  mouth  of  the  econo- 
mist. "  Value  " — {i.e.,  exchange  value)  "  is  a  property  of  things, 
riches  " — {i,e.,  use-value)  "  of  man.  Value,  in  this  sense,  neces- 
sarily implies  exchanges,  riches  do  not."^  "Riches"  (use-value) 
*'  are  the  attribute  of  men,  value  is  the  attribute  of  commodi- 
ties. A  man  or  a  community  is  rich,  a  pearl  or  a  diamond  is 
valuable  ...  A  pearl  or  a  diamond  is  valuable  "  as  a  pearl  or 
diamond.^  So  far  no  chemist  has  ever  discovered  exchange 
value  either  in  a  pearl  or  a  diamond.  The  economical  dis- 
coverers of  this  chemical  element,  who  by-the-bye  lay  special 
claim  to  critical  acumen,  find  however  that  the  use-value  of 
objects  belongs  to  them  independently  of  their  material  pro- 
perties, while  their  value,  on  the  other  hand,  forms  a  part  of 
them  as  objects.  What  confirms  them  in  this  view,  is  the 
peculiar  circumstance  that  the  use- value  of  objects  is  realised 
without  exchange,  by  means  of  a  direct  relation  between  the 
objects  and  man,  while,  on  the  other  hand,  their  value  is  real- 
ised only  by  exchange,  that  is,  by  means  of  a  social  process. 
Who  fails  here  to  call  to  mind  our  good  friend,  Dogberry,  who 
informs  neighbour  Seacoal,  that,  "  To  be  a  well-favoured  man 
is  the  gift  of  fortune  ;  but  reading  and  writing  comes  by 
nature." 

1  Observations  on  certain  verbal  disputes  in  Pol.  Econ. ,  particularly  relating  to  value 
and  to  demand  and  supply.     Lond. ,  1821,  p.  16. 

2  S.  Bailey,  1.  c,  p.  165. 

3  The  author  of  "  Observations  "  and  S.  Bailey  accuse  Eicardo  of  converting  ex- 
change value  from  something  relative  into  something  absolute.  The  opposite  is  the 
fact.  He  has  explained  the  apparent  relation  between  objects,  such  as  diamonds  and 
pearls,  in  which  relation  they  appear  as  exchange  values,  and  disclosed  the  true  rela- 
tion hidden  behind  the  appearances,  namely,  their  relation  to  each  other  as  mere 
expressions  of  human  labour.  If  the  followers  of  Ricardo  answer  Bailey  somewhat 
rudely,  and  by  no  means  convincingly,  the  reason  is  to  be  sought  in  this,  that  they 
were  unable  to  find  in  Ricardo's  own  works  any  key  to  the  hidden  relations  existing 
between  value  and  its  form,  exchange  value. 


56  Capitalist  Production, 


\ 


I 


CHAPTER  11. 

EXCHANGE. 

It  is  plain  that  commodities  cannot  go  to  market  and  make 
exchanges  of  their  own  account.  We  mast,  therefore,  have 
recourse  to  their  guardians,  who  are  also  their  owners.  Com- 
modities are  things,  and  therefore  without  power  of  resistance 
against  man.  If  they  are  wanting  in  docility  he  can  use  force ; 
in  other  words,  he  can  take  possession  of  them.^  In  order  that 
these  objects  may  enter  into  i elation  with  each  other  as 
commodities,  their  guardians  must  place  themselves  in  relation 
to  one  another,  as  persons  whose  will  resides  in  those  objects, 
and  must  behave  in  such  a  way  that  each  does  not  appropriate 
the  commodity  of  the  other,  and  part  with  his  own,  except  by 
means  of  an  act  done  hy  mutual  consent.  They  must,  there- 
fore, mutually  recognise  in  each  other  the  rights  of  private 
proprietors.  This  juridical  relation,  which  thus  expresses  itself 
in  a  contract,  whether  such  contract  be  part  of  a  developed 
legal  system  or  not,  is  a  relation  between  two  wills,  and  is  but 
the  reflex  of  the  real  economical  relation  between  the  two.  It 
is  this  economical  relation  that  determines  the  subject  matter 
comprised  in  each  such  juridical  act.^  The  persons  exist  for 
one  another  merely  as  representatives  of,   and,  therefore,  as 

1  In  the  12th  century,  so  renowned  for  its  piety,  they  included  amongst  com- 
modities some  very  delicate  things.  Thus  a  French  poet  of  the  period  enumerates 
amongst  the  goods  to  be  found  in  the  market  of  Landit,  not  only  clothing,  shoes, 
leather,  agricultural  implements,  &c.,  but  also  "  femmes  foUes  de  leur  corps." 

2  Proudhon  begins  by  taking  his  ideal  of  justice,  of  "justice  eternelle,"  from 
the  juridical  relations  that  correspond  to  the  production  of  commodities  :  thereby, 
it  may  be  noted,  he  proves,  to  the  consolation  of  all  good  citizens,  that  the 
production  of  commodities  is  a  form  of  ijroduction  as  everlasting  as  justice. 
Then  he  turns  round  and  seeks  to  reform  the  actual  production  of  commodities,  and 
the  actual  legal  system  corresponding  thereto,  in  accordance  with  this  ideal.  What 
opinion  should  we  have  of  a  chemist,  who,  instead  of  studying  the  actual  laws  of  the 
molecular  changes  in  the  composition  and  decomposition  of  matter,  and  on  that 
foundation  solving  definite  problems,  claimed  to  regulate  the  composition  and 
•lecomposition  of  matter  by  means  of  the  "eternal  ideas,"  of  "naturalite"  and 
"affinite?"  Do  we  really  know  any  more  about  "  usury,"  when  we  say  it  contra- 
dicts "justice  eternelle,"  "equit6  eternelle,"  "  mutualite  eternelle,"  and  other 
"  verites  eternelles  "  than  the  fathers  of  the  church  did  when  they  said  it  was  incom- 
patible with  "  grS,ce  eternelle,"  "  foi  eternelle,"  and  "  la  volonte  eternelle  de  Dieu  ?" 


Exchange.  57 

owners  of,  commodities.  In  the  course  of  our  investigation  we 
shall  find,  in  general,  that  the  characters  who  appear  on  the 
economic  stage  are  but  the  personifications  of  the  economical 
relations  that  exist  between  them. 

What  chiefly  distinguishes  a  commodity  from  its  owner  is  the 
fact,  that  it  looks  upon  every  other  commodity  as  but  the  form 
of  appearance  of  its  own  value.  A  born  leveller  and  a  cynic, 
it  is  always  ready  to  exchange  not  only  soul,  but  body,  with 
any  and  every  other  commodity,  be  the  same  more  repulsive 
than  Maritornes  herself.  The  owner  makes  up  for  this  lack  in 
the  commodity  of  a  sense  of  the  concrete,  by  his  own  five  and 
more  senses.  His  commodity  possesses  for  himself  no  im- 
mediate use- value.  Otherwise,  he  woul.d  not  bring  it  to  the 
market.  It  has  use-value  for  others  ;  but  for  himself  its  only 
direct  use-value  is  that  of  being  a  depository  of  exchange 
value,  and,  consequently,  a  means  of  exchange.^  Therefore, 
he  makes  up  his  mind  to  part  with  it  for  commodities  whose 
value  in  use  is  of  service  to  him.  All  commodities  are  non-use- 
values  for  their  owners,  aud  use- values  for  their  non-owners. 
Consequently,  they  must  all  change  hands.  But  this  change 
of  hands  is  what  constitutes  their  exchange,  and  the  latter 
puts  them  in  relation  with  each  other  as  values,  and  realises 
them  as  values.  Hence  commodities  must  be  realised  as  values 
before  they  can  be  realised  as  use-values. 

On  the  other  hand,  they  must  show  that  they  are  use- 
values  before  they  can  be  realised  as  values.  For  the  labour 
spent  upon  them  counts  effectively,  only  in  so  far  as  it  is  spent 
in  a  form  that  is  useful  for  others.  Whether  that  labour  is  use- 
ful for  others,  and  its  product  consequently  capable  of  satisfying 
the  wants  of  others,  can  be  proved  only  by  the  act  of  exchange. 

Every  owner  of  a  commodity  wishes  to  part  with  it  in  ex- 
change only  for  those  commodities  whose  use-value  satisfies 
some  want  of  his.     Looked  at  in  this  way,  exchange  is  for 

1  "For  two-fold  is  the  use  of  every  object.  .  .  .  The  one  is  peculiar  to  the 
object  as  such,  the  other  is  not,  as  a  sandal  which  may  be  worn,  and  is  also  exchange- 
able. Both  are  uses  of  the  sandal,  for  even  he  who  exchanges  the  sandal  for  the 
money  or  food  he  is  in  want  of,  makes  use  of  the  sandal  as  a  sandal.  But  not  in 
its  natural  way.  For  it  has  not  been  made  for  the  sake  of  being  exchanged.' 
(Aristoteles,  de  Eep.,  1.  i.  c.  9.) 


58  Capitalist  Production, 

him  simply  a  private  transaction.  On  the  other  hand,  he  de- 
sires to  realise  the  value  of  his  commodity,  to  convert  it  into 
any  other  suitable  commodity  of  equal  value,  irrespective  of 
whether  his  own  commodity  has  or  has  not  any  use-value  for 
the  owner  of  the  other.  From  this  point  of  view,  exchange  is 
for  him  a  social  transaction  of  a  general  character.  But  one 
and  the  same  set  of  transactions  cannot  be  simultaneously  for 
all  owners  of  commodities  both  exclusively  private  and  ex- 
clusively social  and  general. 

Let  us  look  at  the  matter  a  little  closer.  To  the  owner  of  a 
commodity,  every  other  commodity  is,  in  regard  to  his  own,  a 
particular  equivalent,  and  consequently  his  own  commodity  is 
the  universal  equivalent  for  all  the  others.  But  since  this 
applies  to  every  owner,  there  is,  in  fact,  no  commodity  acting 
as  universal  equivalent,  and  the  relative  value  of  commodities 
possesses  no  general  form  under  which  they  can  be  equated  as 
values  and  have  the  magnitude  of  their  values  compared.  So 
far,  therefore,  they  do  not  confront  each  other  as  commodities, 
but  only  as  products  or  use-values.  In  their  difficulties  our 
commodity-owners  think  like  Faust :  "  Im  Anfang  war  die 
That."  They  therefore  acted  and  transacted  before  they 
thought.  Instinctively  they  conform  to  the  laws  imposed  by 
the  nature  of  commodities.  They  cannot  bring  their  com- 
modities into  relation  as  values,  and  therefore  as  commodities, 
except  by  comparing  them  with  some  one  other  commodity 
as  the  universal  equivalent.  That  we  saw  from  the  analysis 
of  a  commodity.  But  a  particular  commodity  cannot  become 
the  universal  equivalent  except  by  a  social  act.  The  social 
action  therefore  of  all  other  commodities,  sets  apart  the  par- 
ticular commodity  in  which  they  all  represent  their  values. 
Thereby  the  bodily  form  of  this  commodity  becomes  the  form 
of  the  socially  recognised  universal  equivalent.  To  be  the 
universal  equivalent,  becomes,  by  this  social  process,  the 
specific  function  of  the  commodity  thus  excluded  by  the  rest. 
Thus  it  becomes — money.  "Illi  unum  consilium  habent  et 
virtutem  et  potestatem  suam  bestise  tradunt.  Et  ne  quis 
possit  emere  aut  vendere,  nisi  qui  habet  characterem  aut 
nomen  bestise,  aut  numerum  nominis  ejus."     {Apocalypse.) 


Exchange.  59 

Money  is  a  crystal  formed  of  necessity  in  the  course  of  the 
exchanges,  whereby  different  products  of  labour  are  practically 
equated  to  one  another  and  thus  by  practice  converted  into 
commodities.  The  historical  progress  and  extension  of  ex- 
changes develops  the  contrast,  latent  in  commodities,  between 
use-value  and  value.  The  necessity  for  giving  an  external 
expression  to  this  contrast  for  the  purposes  of  commercial  in- 
tercourse, urges  on  the  establishment  of  an  independent  form 
of  value,  and  finds  no  rest  until  it  is  once  for  all  satisfied  by 
the  differentiation  of  commodities  into  commodities  and  money. 
At  the  same  rate,  then,  as  the  conversion  of  products  into 
commodities  is  being  accomplished,  so  also  is  the  conversion  of 
one  special  commodity  into  money.^ 

The  direct  barter  of  products  attains  the  elementary  form 
of  the  relative  expression  of  value  in  one  respect,  but  not  in 
another.  That  form  is  x  Commodity  A  =  y  Commodity  B. 
The  form  of  direct  barter  is  x  use- value  A  =  y  use-value  B.^ 
The  articles  A  and  B  in  this  case  are  not  as  yet  commodities, 
but  become  so  only  by  the  act  of  barter.  The  first  step  made 
by  an  object  of  utility  towards  acquiring  exchange- value 
is  when  it  forms  a  non-use-value  for  its  owner,  and  that 
happens  when  it  forms  a  superfluous  portion  of  some  article 
required  for  his  immediate  wants.  Objects  in  themselves  are 
external  to  man,  and  consequently  alienable  by  him.  In  order 
that  this  alienation  may  be  reciprocal,  it  is  only  necessary  for 
men,  by  a  tacit  understanding,  to  treat  each  other  as  private 
owners  of  those  alienable  objects,  and  by  implication  fas  inde- 
pendent individuals.  But  such  a  state  of  reciprocal  indepen- 
dence has  no  existence  in  a  primitive  society  based  on  pro- 
perty in  common,  whether  such  a  society  takes  the  form  of  a 
patriarchal  family,  an  ancient  Indian  community,  or  a  Peruvian 

1  From  this  we  may  form  an  estimate  of  the  shrewdness  of  the  petit-bourgeoi» 
socialism,  which,  while  perpetuating  the  production  of  commodities,  aims  at  abolishing 
the  "antagonism  "  between  money  and  commodities,  and  consequently,  since  money 
exists  only  by  virtue  of  this  antagonism,  at  abolishing  money  itself.  We  might  just 
as  well  try  to  retain  Catholicism  without  the  Pope.  For  more  on  this  point  see  my 
work,  "  Zur  Kritik  der  Pol.  Oekon.,"  p.  61,  s.q. 

2  So  long  as,  instead  of  two  distinct  use-values  being  exchanged,  a  chaotic  mass  of 
articles  are  offered  as  the  equivalent  of  a  single  article,  which  is  often  the  case  with 
savages,  even  the  direct  barter  of  products  is  in  its  first  infancy. 


6o  Capitalist  Production. 

Inca  State.  The  exchange  of  commodities,  therefore,  first 
begins  on  the  boundaries  of  such  communities,  at  their  points 
of  contact  with  other  similar  communities,  or  with  members  of 
the  latter.  So  soon,  however,  as  products  once  become  com- 
modities in  the  external  relations  of  a  community,  they  also, 
by  reaction,  become  so  in  its  internal  intercourse.  The  pro- 
yjortions  in  which  they  are  exchangeable  are  at  first  quite  a 
matter  of  chance.  What  makes  them  exchangeable  is  the 
mutual  desire  of  their  owners  to  alienate  them.  Meantime  the 
need  for  foreign  objects  of  utility  gradually  establishes  itself 
"The  constant  repetition  of  exchange  makes  it  a  normal  social 
:act.  In  the  course  of  time,  therefore,  some  portion  at  least  of 
^the  products  of  labour  must  be  produced  with  a  special  view 
to  exchanofe.  From  that  moment  the  distinction  becomes 
firmly  established  between  the  utility  of  an  object  for  the  pur- 
poses of  consumption,  and  its  utility  for  the  purposes  of  ex- 
change. Its  use- value  becomes  distinguished  from  its  exchange 
value.  On  the  other  hand,  the  quantitative  proportion  in 
which  the  articles  are  exchangeable,  becomes  dependent  on 
their  production  itself.  Custom  stamps  them  as  values  with 
definite  magnitudes. 

In  the  direct  barter  of  products,  each  commodity  is  directly 
a  means  of  exchange  to  its  owner,  and  to  all  other  persons  an 
equivalent,  but  that  only  in  so  far  as  it  has  use-value  for  them. 
At  this  stage,  therefore,  the  articles  exchanged  do  not  acquire 
a  value-form  independent  of  their  own  use-value,  or  of  the 
individual  needs  of  the  exchangers.  The  necessity  for  a  value- 
form  grows  with  the  increasing  number  and  variety  of  the 
commodities  exchanged.  The  problem  and  the  means  of  solu- 
tion arise  simultaneously.  Commodity-owners  never  equate 
their  own  commodities  to  those  of  others,  and  exchange  them 
on  a  large  scale,  without  different  kinds  of  commodities  belong- 
ing to  different  owners  being  exchangeable  for,  and  equated  as 
values  to,  one  and  the  same  special  article.  Such  last-men- 
tioned article,  by  becoming  the  equivalent  of  various  other 
commodities,  acquires  at  once,  though  within  narrow  limits, 
the  character  of  a  general  social  equivalent.  This  character 
comes  and  goes  with  the  momentary  social  acts  that  called  it 


Exchange,  6i 

into  life.  In  turns  and  transiently  it  attaches  itself  first  to  this 
and  then  to  that  commodity.  But  with  the  development  oi 
exchange  it  fixes  itself  firmly  and  exclusively  to  particular 
sorts  of  commodities,  and  becomes  crystallised  by  assuming  the 
money-form.  The  particular  kind  of  commodity  to  which  it 
sticks  is  at  first  a  matter  of  accident.  Nevertheless  there  are- 
two  circumstances  whose  influence  is  decisive.  The  money- 
form  attaches  itself  either  to  the  most  important  articles  of  ex- 
change from  outside,  and  these  in  fact  are  primitive  and  natural 
forms  in  which  the  exchange-value  of  home  products  finds  ex- 
pression ;  or  else  it  attaches  itself  to  the  object  of  utility 
that  forms,  like  cattle,  the  chief  portion  of  indigenous  alienable 
wealth.  Nomad  races  are  the  first  to  develop  the  money-form, 
because  all  their  worldly  goods  consist  of  moveable  objects 
and  are  therefore  directly  alienable  ;  and  because  their  mode  of 
life,  by  continually  bringing  them  into  contact  with  foreign  com- 
munities, solicits  the  exchange  of  products.  Man  has  often 
made  man  himself,  under  the  form  of  slaves,  serve  as  the  pri- 
mitive material  of  money,  but  has  never  used  land  for  that 
purpose.  Such  an  idea  could  only  spring  up  in  a  bourgeois 
society  already  well  developed.  It  dates  from  the  last  third  of 
the  17th  century,  and  the  first  attempt  to  put  it  in  practice 
on  a  national  scale  was  made  a  century  afterwards,  during  the 
French  bourgeois  revolution. 

In  proportion  as  exchange  bursts  its  local  bonds,  and  the 
value  of  commodities  more  and  more  expands  into  an  embodi- 
ment  of  human  labour  in  the  abstract,  in  the  same  proportion 
the  character  of  money  attaches  itself  to  commodities  that  are 
by  nature  fitted  to  perform  the  social  function  of  a  universal 
equivalent.     Those  commodities  are  the  precious  metals. 

The  truth  of  the  proposition  that,  "  although  gold  and  silver 
are  not  by  nature  money,  money  is  by  nature  gold  and 
silver,"  ^  is  shown  by  the  fitness  of  the  physical  properties  of 
these  metals  for  the  functions  of  money.^  Up  to  this  point, 
however,  we  are  acquainted  only  with  one  function  of  mone}^ 

1  Karl  Marx.  1.   c.   p.   135.      "  I  metalli.  .  .  naturalmente  moneta,"  (Galiani. 
**  Delia  moneta  "  in  Custodi's  Collection  :  Parte  Moderna  t.  iii.). 

2  For  further  details  on  this  subject  see  in  my  work  cited  above,  the  chapter  on 
**  The  precious  metals." 


62  Capitalist  Production. 

namely,  to  serve  as  the  form  of  manifestation  of  the  value  of 
commodities,  or  as  the  material  in  which  the  magnitudes  of 
their  values  are  socially  expressed.  An  adequate  form  of 
manifestation  of  value,  a  fit  embodiment  of  abstract,  undiffer- 
entiated, and  therefore  equal  human  labour,  that  material 
alone  can  be  whose  every  sample  exhibits  the  same  uniform 
qualities.  On  the  other  hand,  since  the  difference  between  the 
magnitudes  of  value  is  purely  quantitative,  the  money  com- 
modity must  be  susceptible  of  merely  quantitative  differences, 
must  therefore  be  divisible  at  will,  and  equally  capable  of  being 
re-united.      Gold  and  silver  possess  these  properties  by  nature. 

The  use-value  of  the  money  commodity  becomes  twofold. 
In  addition  to  its  special  use-value  as  a  commodity  (gold, 
for  instance,  serving  to  stop  teeth,  to  form  the  raw  material  of 
articles  of  luxury,  &c.),  it  acquires  a  formal  use-value,  origina- 
ting in  its  specific  social  function. 

Since  all  commodities  are  merely  particular  equivalents  of 
money,  the  latter  being  their  universal  equivalent,  they,  with 
regard  to  the  latter  as  the  universal  commodity,  play  the  parts 
of  particular  commodities.^ 

We  have  seen  that  the  money-form  is  but  the  reflex,  thrown 
upon  one  single  commodity,  of  the  value  relations  between  all  the 
rest.  That  money  is  a  commodity^  is  therefore  a  new  discovery 
only  for  those  who,  when  they  analyse  it,  start  from  its  fully 
developed  shape.  The  act  of  exchange  gives  to  the  commodity 
converted  into  money,  not  its  value,  but  its  specific  value-form. 
By  confounding  these  two  distinct  things  some  writers  have 
been  led  to  hold  that  the  value  of  gold  and  silver  is  imagi- 

1  "  II  danaro  e  la  merce  universale  (Verri,  l.'c,  p.  IG). 

2  "  Silver  and  gold  themselves  (which  we  may  call  by  the  general  name  of  bullion), 
are  .  .  .  commodities  .  .  .  rising  and  falling  in  .  .  .  value.  .  .  Bullion,  then,  may 
be  reckoned  to  be  of  higher  value  where  the  smaller  weight  will  purchase  the  greater 
quantity  of  the  product  or  manufacture  of  the  countrey,"  &c.  ("A  Discourse  of  the 
General  Notions  of  Money,  Trade,  and  Exchange,  as  they  stand  in  relations  to  each 
other."  By  a  Merchant.  Lond.,  1695,  p.  7).  "  Silver  and  gold,  coined  or  uncoined, 
though  they  are  used  for  a  measure  of  all  other  things,  are  no  less  a  commodity  than 
wine,  oyl,  tobacco,  cloth,  or  stuffs."  ("A  Discourse  concerning  Trade,  and  that  in 
j)articular  of  the  East  Indies,"  &c.  London,  1689,  p.  2).  "  The  stock  and  riches  of 
the  kingdom  cannot  properly  be  confined  to  money,  nor  ought  gold  and  silver  to  be 
excluded  from  being  merchandize."  ("A  Treatise  concerning  the  East  India  Trade 
being  a  most  profitable  Trade."    London,  1680,  Keprint  1096,  p.  4). 


Exchange.  63 

nary.^  The  fact  that  money  can,  in  certain  functions,  be  replaced 
by  mere  symbols  of  itself,  gave  rise  to  that  other  mistaken  notion, 
that  it  is  itself  a  mere  symbol.  Nevertheless  under  this  error 
lurked  a  presentiment  that  the  money-form  of  an  object  is  not 
an  inseparable  part  of  tha,t  object,  but  is  simply  the  form  under 
which  certain  social  relations  manifest  themselves.  In  this 
sense  every  commodity  is  a  symbol,  since,  in  so  far  as  it  is 
value,  it  is  only  the  material  envelope  of  the  human  labour 
spent  upon  it.^  But  if  it  be  declared  that  the  social  characters 
assumed  by  objects,  or  the  material  forms  assumed  by  the 
social  qualities  of  labour  under  the  regime  of  a  definite  mode  of 
production,  are  mere  symbols,  it  is  in  the  same  breath  also 
declared  that  these  characteristics  are  arbitrary  fictions  sanc- 
tioned by  the  so-called  universal  consent  of  mankind.     This 

1  "  L'oro  e  I'argento  hanno  valore  come  metalli  anteriore  all'  esser  moneta." 
{Galiani,  I.e.).  Locke  says,  " The  universal  consent  of  mankind  gave  to  silver,  on 
account  of  its  qualities  which  made  it  suitable  for  money,  an  imaginary  value."  Law, 
on  the  other  hand,  "  How  could  different  nations  give  an  imaginary  value  to  any 
single  thing  ...  or  how  could  this  imaginary  value  have  maintained  itself  ?  "  But 
the  following  shows  how  little  he  himself  understood  about  the  matter  :  "Silver  was 
exchanged  in  proportion  to  the  value  in  use  it  possessed,  consequently  in  isroportion  to 
its  real  value.  By  its  adoption  as  money  it  received  an  additional  value  (une  valeur 
additionnelle) "  (Jean  Law:  "Considerations  sur  le  numeraire  et  le  commerce"  in 
E.  Daire's  Edit,  of  '*  Economistes  Financiers  du  XVIII.  siecle.,"  p.  470). 

2  "  L'Argent  en  (des  denrees)  est  le  signe."  (V.  de  Forbonnais  :  "  Elements  du  Com- 
merce, Nouv.  Edit.  Leyde,  1776,"  t.  II.,  p.  143).  "  Comme  signe  il  est  attir^  par  les 
denrees."  (I.e.,  p.  155).  "  L'argent  est  im  signe  d' une  chose  et  la  repr^sente."  (Mon- 
tesquieu :  "  Esprit  des  Lois,"  Oeuvres,  Lond.  1767,  t.  II.,  p.  2).  "L'argent  n'est  pas 
simple  signe,  car  il  est  lui-meme  richesse ;  il  ne  represente  pas  les  valeurs,  il  les 
6quivaut."  (Le  Trosne,  I.e.,  p.  910).  "  The  notion  of  value  contemplates  the  valuable 
article  as  a  mere  symbol ;  the  article  counts  not  for  what  it  is,  but  for  what  it  is 
worth."  (Hegel,  I.e.,  p.  100).  Lawyers  started  long  before  economists  the  idea  that 
money  is  a  mere  symbol,  and  that  the  value  of  the  precious  metals  is  purely  imaginary. 
This  they  did  in  the  sycophantic  service  of  the  crowned  heads,  supporting  the  right 
of  the  latter  to  debase  the  coinage,  during  the  whole  of  the  middle  ages,  by  the  tradi- 
tions of  the  Roman  Empire  and  the  conceptions  of  money  to  be  found  in  the  Pandects. 
"Qu'  aucun  puisse  ni  doive  faire  doute,"  says  an  apt  scholar  of  theirs,  Philip  of 
Valois,  in  a  decree  of  1346,  "  que  k  nous  et  £l  notre  majesty  royale  n'  appartiennent 
seulement  .  .  .  le  mestier,  le  fait,  I'^tat,  la  provision  et  toute  I'ordonnanee  des 
monnaies,  de  donner  tel  cours,  et  pour  tel  prix  comme  il  nous  plait  et  bon  nous 
semble."  It  was  a  maxim  of  the  Roman  Law  that  the  value  of  money  was  fixed  by 
decree  of  the  emperor.  It  was  expressly  forbidden  to  treat  money  as  a  commodity. 
"  Petunias  vero  nulli  emere  fas  erit,  nam  in  usu  publico  constitutas  oportet  non  esse 
mercem."  Some  good  work  on  this  question  has  been  done  by  G.  F.  Pagnini : 
"Saggiosopiailgiusto  pregio  delle  cose,  1751 "  ;  Custodi  "Parte  Moderna,"  t.  II. 
In  the  second  part  of  his  work  Pagnini  directs  his  polemics  especially  against  the 
lawyers. 


64  Capitalist  Production. 

suited  the  mode  of  explanation  in  favour  during  the  18th 
century.  Unable  to  account  for  the  origin  of  the  puzzling 
forms  assumed  by  social  relations  between  man  and  man,  people 
sought  to  denude  them  of  their  strange  appearance  by  ascribing 
to  them  a  conventional  origin. 

It  has  already  been  remarked  above  that  the  equivalent  form 
of  a  commodity  does  not  imply  the  determination  of  the  magni- 
tude of  its  value.  Therefore,  although  we  may  be  aware  that  gold 
is  money,  and  consequently  directly  exchangeable  for  all  other 
commodities,  yet  that  fact  by  no  means  tells  how  much  10  lbs. 
for  instance,  of  gold  is  worth.  Money,  like  every  other  com- 
modity, cannot  express  the  magnitude  of  its  value  except 
relatively  in  other  commodities.  This  value  is  determined  by 
the  labour-time  required  for  its  production,  and  is  expressed  by 
the  quantity  of  any  other  commodity  that  costs  the  same 
amout  of  labour-time.^  Such  quantitative  determination  of  its 
relative  value  takes  place  at  the  source  of  its  production  by 
means  of  barter.  Wlien  it  steps  into  circulation  as  money,  its 
value  is  already  given.  In  the  last  decades  of  the  17th 
century  it  had  already  been  shown  that  money  is  a  commodity^ 
but  this  step  marks  only  the  infancy  of  the  analysis.  The 
difficulty  lies,  not  in  comprehending  that  money  is  a  commo- 
dity, but  in  discovering  how,  why,  and  by  what  means  a  com- 
modity becomes  money.^ 

1  **  If  a  man  can  bring  to  London  an  ounce  of  Silver  out  of  the  Earth  in  Peru,  in  the 
same  time  that  he  can  produce  a  bushel  of  Corn,  then  the  one  is  the  natural  price  of 
the  other ;  now,  if  by  reason  of  new  or  more  easie  mines  a  man  can  procure  two 
ounces  of  silver  as  easily  as  he  formerly  did  one,  the  corn  will  be  as  cheap  at  ten 
shillings  the  bushel  as  it  was  before  at  five  shillings,  cseteris  paribus."  William 
Petty  :  "  A  Treatise  on  Taxes  and  Contributions."    Lond.,  1662,  p.  32. 

2  The  learned  Professor  Eoscher,  after  first  informing  us  that  "the  false  definitions 
of  money  may  be  divided  into  two  main  groups  :  those  which  make  it  more,  and 
those  which  make  it  less,  than  a  commodity, "  gives  us  a  long  and  very  mixed  cata- 
logue of  works  on  the  nature  of  money,  from  which  it  appears  that  he  has  not  the 
remotest  idea  of  the  real  history  of  the  theory  ;  and  then  he  moralises  thus  :  "  For 
the  rest,  it  is  not  to  be  denied  that  most  of  the  later  economists  do  not  bear  sufficiently 
in  mind  the  peculiarities  that  distinguish  money  from  other  commodities  "  (it  is  then, 
after  all,  either  more  or  less  than  a  commodity  !)  .  .  .  "So  far,  the  semi-mercantilist 
reaction  of  Ganilh  is  not  altogether  without  foundation."  (Wilhelm  Eoscher  :  "  Die 
Grundlagen  der  Nationaloekonomie, "  3rd  Edn.,  1858,  pp.  277-210.)  More!  less! 
not  sufficiently  !  so  far  !  not  altogether  !  Wliat  clearness  and  precision  of  ideas  and 
language  !  And  such  eclectic  professorial  twaddle  is  modestly  baptised  by  Mr. 
Eoscher,  "the  anatomico-physiological  method  "  of  political  economy  !  One  discovery 
however,  he  must  have  credit  for,  namely,  that  money  is  "  a  pleasant  commodity." 


Exchange,  65 

We  have  already  seen,  from  the  most  elementary  expression 
of  vahie,  x  commodity  A  z  y  commodity  B,  that  the  object  in 
which  the  magnitude  of  the  value  of  another  object  is  repre- 
sented, appears  to  have  the  equivalent  form  independently  ot 
this  relation,  as  a  social  property  given  to  it  by  Nature.  We 
followed  up  this  false  appearance  to  its  final  establishment, 
which  is  complete  so  soon  as  the  universal  equivalent  form 
becomes  identified  with  the  bodily  form  of  a  particular  com- 
modity, and  thus  crystallised  into  the  money-form.  What 
appears  to  happen  is,  not  that  gold  becomes  money,  in  conse- 
quence of  all  other  commodities  expressing  their  values  in  it, 
but,  on  the  contrary,  that  all  other  commodities  universally 
express  their  values  in  gold,  because  it  is  money.  The  inter- 
mediate steps  of  the  process  vanish  in  the  result  and  leave  no 
trace  behind.  Commodities  find  their  own  value  already  com- 
pletely represented,  without  any  initiative  on  their  part,  in 
another  commodity  existing  in  company  with  them.  These 
objects,  gold  and  silver,  just  as  they  come  out  of  the  bowels  of 
the  earth,  are  forthwith  the  direct  incarnation  of  all  human 
labour.  Hence  the  magic  of  money.  In  the  form  of  society 
now  under  consideration,  the  behaviour  of  men  in  the  social 
process  of  production  is  purely  atomic.  Hence  their  relations 
to  each  other  in  production  assume  a  material  character  inde- 
pendent of  their  control  and  conscious  individual  action. 
These  facts  manifest  themselves  at  first  by  products  as  a  general 
rule  taking  the  form  of  commodities.  We  have  seen  how  the 
progressive  development  of  a  society  of  commodity-producers 
stamps  one  privileged  commodity  with  the  character  of  money. 
Hence  the  riddle  presented  by  money  is  but  the  riddle  pre- 
sented by  commodities;  only  it  now  strikes  us  in  its  most 
glaring  form. 


66       '  Capitalist  Prod^iction. 

CHAPTER  III. 

MONEY,   OR  THE  CIRCULATION   OF  COMMODITIES. 

SECTION   1. — THE   MEASURE   OF   VALUES. 

Throughout  this  work,  I  assume,  for  the  sake  of  simplicity, 
gold  as  the  money-commodity. 

The  first  chief  function  of  money  is  to  supply  commodities 
with  the  material  for  the  expression  of  their  values,  or  to  re- 
present their  values  as  magnitudes  of  the  same  denomination, 
qualitatively  equal,  and  quantitatively  comparable.  It  thus 
serves  as  a  universal  measure  of  value.  And  only  by  virtue  of 
this  function  does  gold,  the  equivalent  commodity  'par  excel- 
lence,  become  money. 

It  is  not  money  that  renders  commodities  commensurable. 
Just  the  contrary.  It  is  because  all  commodities,  as  values,  are 
realised  human  labour,  and  therefore  commensurable,  that  their 
values  can  be  measured  by  one  and  the  same  special  commodity, 
and  the  latter  be  converted  into  the  common  measure  of  their 
values,  ie.y  into  money.  Money  as  a  measure  of  value,  is  the 
phenomenal  form  that  must  of  necessity  be  assumed  by  that 
measure  of  value  which  is  immanent  in  commodities,  labour- 
time.  ^ 

The  expression  of  the  value  of  a  commodity  in  gold — x 
commodity  A  =  y   money-commodity — is    its   money-form   or 

1  The  question — Why  does  not  money  directly  represent  labour-time,  so  that  a 
piece  of  paper  may  represent,  for  instance,  x  hour's  labour,  is  at  bottom  the  same  as 
the  question  why,  given  the  production  of  commodities,  must  products  take  the  form 
of  commodities  ?  This  is  evident,  since  their  taking  the  form  of  commodities  implies 
their  differentiation  into  commodities  and  money.  Or,  why  cannot  private  labour — 
labour  for  the  account  of  private  individuals — be  treated  as  its  opposite,  immediate 
social  labour?  I  have  elsewhere  examined  thoroughly  the  Utopian  idea  of  "labour- 
money"  in  a  society  founded  on  the  production  of  commodities  (1.  c,  p.  61,  seq.). 
On  this  point  I  will  only  say  further,  that  Owen's  "labour-money,"  for  instance,  is 
no  more  "money"  than  a  ticket  for  the  theatre.  Owen  presupposes  directly 
associated  labour,  a  form  of  production  that  is  entirely  inconsistent  with  the  produc- 
tion of  commodities.  The  certificate  of  labour  is  merely  evidence  of  the  part  taken 
by  the  individual  in  the  common  labour,  and  of  his  right  to  a  certain  portion  of  the 
common  produce  destined  for  consumption.  But  it  never  enters  into  Owen's  head  to 
presuppose  the  production  of  commodities,  and  at  the  same  time,  by  juggling  with 
money,  to  try  to  evade  the  necessary  conditions  of  that  production. 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.       6y 

price.  A  single  equation,  such  as  1  ton  of  iron  =  2  ounces  of 
gold,  now  suffices  to  express  the  value  of  the  iron  in  a  socially 
valid  manner.  There  is  no  longer  any  need,  for  this  equation 
to  figure  as  a  link  in  the  chain  of  equations  that  express  the 
values  of  all  other  commodities,  because  the  equivalent  com- 
modity, gold,  now  has  the  character  of  money.  The  general 
form  of  relative  value  has  resumed  its  original  shape  of  simple 
or  isolated  relative  value.  On  the  other  hand,  the  expanded 
expression  of  relative  value,  the  endless  series  of  equations,  has 
now  become  the  form  peculiar  to  the  relative^  value  of  the 
money-commodity.  The  series  itself,  too,  is  now  given,  and 
has  social  recognition  in  the  prices  of  actual  commodities.  We 
have  only  to  read  the  quotations  of  a  price-list  backwards,  to 
find  the  magnitude  of  the  value  of  money  expressed  in  all  sorts 
of  commodities.  But  money  itself  has  no  price.  In  order  to 
put  it  on  an  equal  footing  with  all  other  commodities  in  this 
respect,  we  should  be  obliged  to  equate  it  to  itself  as  its  own 
equivalent. 

The  price  or  money-form  of  commodities  is,  like  their  form 
of  value  generally,  a  form  quite  distinct  from  their  palpable 
bodily  form ;  it  is,  therefore,  a  purely  ideal  or  mental  form. 
Although  invisible,  the  value  of  iron,  linen  and  corn  has  actual 
existence  in  these  very  articles :  it  is  ideally  made  perceptible 
by  their  equality  with  gold,  a  relation  that,  so  to  say,  exists 
only  in  their  own  heads.  Their  owner  must,  therefore,  lend 
them  his  tongue,  or  hang  a  ticket  on  them,  before  their  prices 
can  be  communicated  to  the  outside  world.^  Since  the  ex- 
pression of  the  value  of  commodities  in  gold  is  a  merely  ideal 

1  Savages  and  half -civilised  races  use  the  tongue  differently.  Captain  Parry  says 
of  the  inhabitants  on^the  west  coast  of  Baffin's  Bay:  "In  this  case  (he  refers  to 
barter)  they  licked  it  (the  thing  represented  to  them)  twice  to  their  tongues,  after 
which  they  seemed  to  consider  the  bargain  satisfactorily  concluded."  In  the  same 
way,  the  Eastern  Esquimaux  licked  the  articles  they  received  in  exchange.  If  the 
tongue  is  thus  used  in  the  North  as  the  organ  of  appropriation,  no  wonder  that,  in 
the  South,  the  stomach  serves  as  the  organ  of  accumulated  property,  and  that  a 
Kaffir  estimates  the  wealth  of  a  man  by  the  size  of  his  belly.  That  the  Kaffirs  know 
what  they  are  about  is  shown  by  the  following :  at  the  same  time  that  the  official 
British  Health  Keport  of  1864  disclosed  the  deficiency  of  fat-forming  food  among  a 
large  part  of  the  working  class,  a  certain  Dr.  Harvey  (not,  however,  the  celebrated 
discoverer  of  the  circulation  of  the  blood),  made  a  good  thing  by  advertising  recipes 
for  reducing  the  superfluous  fat  of  the  bourgeoisie  and  aristocracy. 


68  Capitalist  Production. 

act,  we  may  use  for  this  purpose  imaginary  or  ideal  money. 
Every  trader  knows,  that  he  is  far  from  having  turned  his 
goods  into  money,  when  he  has  expressed  their  value  in  a  price 
or  in  imaginary  money,  and  that  it  does  not  require  the  least 
bit  of  real  gold,  to  estimate  in  that  metal  millions  of  pounds* 
worth  of  goods.  When,  therefore,  money  serves  as  a  measure 
of  value,  it  is  employed  only  as  imaginary  or  ideal  money. 
This  circumstance  has  given  rise  to  the  wildest  theories.^  But,, 
although  the  money  that  performs  the  functions  of  a  measure 
of  value  is  only  ideal  money,  price  depends  entirel}'-  upon  the 
actual  substance  that  is  money.  The  value,  or  in  other  words, 
the  quantity  of  human  labour  contained  in  a  ton  of  iron,  'y^ 
expressed  in  imagination  by  such  a  quantity  of  the  money- 
commodity  as  contains  the  same  amount  of  labour  as  the  iron. 
According,  therefore,  as  the  measure  of  value  is  gold,  silver,  or 
copper,  the  value  of  the  ton  of  iron  will  be  expressed  by  very 
different  prices,  or  will  be  represented  by  very  different  quan- 
tities of  those  metals  respectively. 

If,  therefore,  two  different  commodities,  such  as  gold  and 
silver,  are  simultaneously  measures  of  value,  all  commodities 
have  two  prices — one  a  gold-price,  the  other  a  silver-price. 
These  exist  quietly  side  by  side,  so  long  as  the  ratio  of  the 
value  of  silver  to  that  of  gold  remains  unchanged,  say,  at  15  :  1. 
Every  change  in  their  ratio  disturbs  the  ratio  which  exists 
between  the  gold-prices  and  the  silver-prices  of  commodities, 
and  thus  proves,  by  facts,  that  a  double  standard  of  value  is 
inconsistent  with  the  functions  of  a  standard.- 

^  See  Karl  Marx:  Zur  Kritik,  &c.  "Theorien  von  der  Masseinheit  des  Geldes," 
p.  53,  seq. 

^  "Wherever  gold  and  silver  have  by  law  been  made  to  j)erform  the  function  of 
money  or  of  a  measure  of  value  side  by  side,  it  has  always  been  tried,  but  in  vain,  to 
treat  them  as  one  and  the  same  material.  To  assume  that  there  is  an  invariable 
ratio  between  the  quantities  of  gold  and  silver  in  which  a  given  quantity  of  labour-time 
is  incorporated,  is  to  assume,  in  fact,  that  gold  and  silver  are  of  one  and  the  same 
material,  and  that  a  given  mass  of  the  less  valuable  metal,  silver,  is  a  constant 
fraction  of  a  given  mass  of  gold.  From  the  reign  of  Edward  III.  to  the  time  of 
George  II.,  the  history  of  money  in  England  consists  of  one  long  series  of  per- 
turbations caused  by  the  clashing  of  the  legally  fixed  ratio  between  the  values  of 
gold  and  silver,  with  the  fluctuations  in  their  real  values.  At  one  time  gold  was  too 
high,  at  another,  silver.  The  metal  that  for  the  time  being  was  estimated  below  its 
value,  was  withdrawn  from  circulation,  melted  and  exported.  The  ratio  between 
the  two  metals  was  then  again  altered  by  law,  but  the  new  nominal  ratio  soon  came 


Moneyy  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.       69 

Commodities  with  definite  prices  present  themselves  under 
the  form :  a  commodity  A  =  x  gold ;  b  commodity  B  =  z  gold; 
<}  commodity  C  =  y  gold,  &;c.,  where  a,  b,  c,  represent  definite 
quantities  of  the  commodities  A,  B,  C  and  x,  z,  y,  definite 
quantities  of  gold.  The  values  of  these  commodities  are, 
therefore,  changed  in  imagination  into  so  many  different 
-quantities  of  gold.  Hence,  in  spite  of  the  confusing  variety  of 
the  commodities  themselves,  their  values  become  magnitudes 
of  the  same  denomination,  gold-magnitudes.  They  are  now 
capable  of  being  compared  with  each  other  and  measured,  and 
the  want  becomes  technically  felt  of  comparing  them  with 
some  fixed  quantity  of  gold  as  a  unit  measure.  This  unit,  by 
subsequent  division  into  aliquot  parts,  becomes  itself  the 
standard  or  scale.  Before  they  become  money,  gold,  silver, 
and  copper  already  possess  such  standard  measures  in  their 
standards  of  weight,  so  that,  for  example,  a  pound  weight, 
while  serving  as  the  unit,  is,  on  the  one  hand,  divisible  into 
ounces,  and,  on  the  other,  may  be  combined  to  make  up 
hundredweights.^  It  is  owing  to  this  that,  in  all  metallic 
currencies,  the  names  given  to  the  standards  of  money  or  of 
price  were  originally  taken  from  the  pre-existing  names  of  the 
standards  of  weight. 

into  conflict  again  with  the  real  one.  In  our  own  times,  the  slight  and  transient 
fall  in  the  value  of  gold  compared  with  silver,  which  was  a  consequence  of  the  Indo- 
Chinese  demand  for  silver,  produced  on  a  far  more  extended  scale  in  France  the  same 
phenomena,  export  of  silver,  and  its  expulsion  from  circulation  by  gold.  During 
the  years  1855,  1856  and  1857,  the  excess  in  France  of  gold-imports  over  gold- 
exports  amounted  to  £41,580,000,  while  the  excess  of  silver-exports  over  silver- 
imports  was  £14,704,000.  In  fact,  in  those  countries  in  which  both  metals  are 
legally  measures  of  value,  and  therefore  both  legal  tender,  so  that  everyone  has  the 
■option  of  paying  in  either  metal,  the  metal  that  rises  in  value  is  at  a  premium,  and, 
like  every  other  commodity,  measures  its  price  in  the  over-estimated  metal  which 
alone  serves  in  reality  as  the  standard  of  value.  The  result  of  all  experience  and 
history  with  regard  to  this  question  is  simply  that,  where  two  commodities  perform 
by  law  the  functions  of  a  measure  of  value,  in  practice  one  alone  maintains  that 
position."    (Karl  Marx,  1.  c.  pp.  52,  53.) 

1  The  peculiar  circumstance,  that  while  the  ounce  of  gold  serves  in  England  as  the 
unit  of  the  standard  of  money,  the  pound  sterling  does  not  form  an  aliquot  part  of  it, 
has  been  explained  as  follows  :  "  Our  coinage  was  originally  adapted  to  the  employ- 
ment of  silver  only,  hence,  an  ounce  of  silver  can  always  be  divided  into  a  certain 
adequate  number  of  pieces  of  coin  ;  but  as  gold  was  introduced  at  a  later  period  into 
a  coinage  adapted  only  to  silver,  an  ounce  of  gold  cannot  be  coined  into  an  aliquot 
number  of  pieces."  Maclaren,  "  A  Sketch  of  the  History  of  the  Currency."  London, 
1858,  p.  16. 


70  Capitalist  Prodtcction, 

As  measure  of  value  and  as  standard  of  price,  money  has  two 
entirely  distinct  functions  to  perform.  It  is  the  measure 
of  value  inasmuch  as  it  is  the  socially  recognised  incarnation 
of  human  labour ;  it  is  the  standard  of  price  inasmuch  as  it  is 
a  fixed  weight  of  metal.  As  the  measure  of  value  it  serves  to* 
convert  the  values  of  all  the  manifold  commodities  into  prices, 
into  imaginary  quantities  of  gold ;  as  the  standard  of  price  it 
measures  those  quantities  of  gold.  The  measure  of  values 
measures  commodities  considered  as  values ;  the  standard  of 
price  measures,  on  the  contrary,  quantities  of  gold  by  a  unit 
quantity  of  gold,  not  the  value  of  one  quantity  of  gold  by  the 
weight  of  another.  In  order  to  make  gold  a  standard  of  price, 
a  certain  weight  must  be  fixed  upon  as  the  unit.  In  this  case, 
as  in  all  cases  of  measuring  quantities  of  the  same  denomina- 
tion, the  establishment  of  an  unvarying  unit  of  measure  is  all- 
important.  Hence,  the  less  the  unit  is  subject  to  variation,  so 
much  the  better  does  the  standard  of  price  fulfil  its  office.  But 
only  in  so  far  as  it  is  itself  a  product  of  labour,  and,  therefore, 
potentially  variable  in  value,  can  gold  serve  as  a  measure  of 
value.^ 

It  is,  in  the  first  place,  quite  clear  that  a  change  in  the  value 
of  gold  does  not,  in  any  way,  affect  its  function  as  a  standard 
of  price.  No  matter  how  this  value  varies,  the  proportions 
between  the  values  of  different  quantities  of  the  metal  remain 
constant.  However  great  the  fall  in  its  value,  12  ounces  of 
gold  still  have  12  times  the  value  of  1  ounce ;  and  in  prices, 
the  only  thing  considered  is  the  relation  between  different 
quantities  of  gold.  Since,  on  the  other  hand,  no  rise  or  fall  in 
the  value  of  an  ounce  of  gold  can  alter  its  weight,  no  alteration 
can  take  place  in  the  weight  of  its  aliquot  parts.  Thus  gold 
always  renders  the  same  service  as  an  invariable  standard  of 
price,  however  much  its  value  may  vary. 

In  the  second  place,  a  change  in  the  value  of  gold  does  not 
interfere  with  its  functions  as  a  measure  of  value.  The  change 
affects  all  commodities  simultaneously,  and,  therefore,  coeteris 
paribus,  leaves  their  relative  values  inter  se,  unaltered,  although 

1  With  English  writers  the  confusion  between  measure  of  value  and  standard  of 
price  (standard  of  value)  is  indescribable.  Their  functions,  as  well  as  their  names,. 
are  constantly  intercharged. 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.      71 

those  values  are  now  expressed  in  higher  or  lower  gold- 
prices. 

Just  as  when  we  estimate  the  value  of  any  commodit}^  by 
a  definite  quantity  of  the  use- value  of  some  other  commodity, 
so  in  estimating  the  value  of  the  former  in  gold.,  we  assume 
nothing  more  than  that  the  production  of  a  given  quantity  of 
gold  costs,  at  the  given  period,  a  given  amount  of  labour.  As 
regards  the  fluctuations  of  prices  generally,  they  are  subject  to 
the  laws  of  elementarj^  relative  value  investigated  in  a  former 
chapter. 

A  general  rise  in  the  prices  of  commodities  can  result  only, 
either  from  a  rise  in  their  values — the  value  of  money  remain- 
ing constant — or  from  a  fall  in  tlie  value  of  money,  the  values 
of  commodities  remaining  constant.  On  the  other  hand,  a 
general  fall  in  prices  can  result  only,  either  from  a  fall  in  the 
values  of  commodities — the  value  of  money  remaining  con- 
stant— or  from  a  rise  in  the  value  of  money,  the  values  of 
commodities  remaining  constant.  It  therefore  by  no  means 
follows,  that  a  rise  in  the  value  of  money  necessarily  implies  a 
proportional  fall  in  the  prices  of  commodities ;  or  that  a  fall  in 
the  value  of  money  implies  a  proportional  rise  in  prices. 
Such  change  of  price  holds  good  only  in  the  case  of  com- 
modities whose  value  remains  constant.  With  those,  for 
example,  whose  value  rises,  simultaneously  with,  and  propor- 
tionally to,  that  of  money,  there  is  no  alteration  in  price. 
And  if  their  value  rise  either  slower  or  faster  than  that  of 
money,  the  fall  or  rise  in  their  prices  will  be  determined  by 
the  difference  between  the  change  in  their  value  and  that  of 
money;  and  so  on. 

Let  us  now  go  back  to  the  consideration  of  the  price-form. 

By  degrees  there  arises  a  discrepancy  between  the  current 
money  names  of  the  various  weights  of  the  precious  metal 
figuring  as  money,  and  the  actual  weights  which  those  names 
originally  represented.  This  discrepancy  is  the  result  of 
liistorical  causes,  among  which  the  chief  are : — (1)  The  im- 
portation of  foreign  money  into  an  imperfectly  developed 
community.  This  happened  in  Kome  in  its  early  days,  where 
gold  and  silver  coins  circulated  at  first  as  foreign  commodities. 


72  Capitalist  Production. 

The  names  of  these  foreign  coins  never  coincide  with  those  ot 
the  indigenous  weights.  (2)  As  wealth  increases,  the  less 
precious  metal  is  thrust  out  by  the  more  precious  from  its  place 
as  a  measure  of  value,  copper  by  silver,  silver  by  gold,  however 
much  this  order  of  sequence  may  be  in  contradiction  with 
poetical  chronology.  ^  The  word  pound,  for  instance,  was  the 
money-name  given  to  an  actual  pound  weight  of  silver.  When 
gold  replaced  silver  as  a  measure  of  value,  the  same  name  was 
applied  according  to  the  ratio  between  the  values  of  silver  and 
gold,  to  perhaps  1-1 5th  of  a  pound  of  gold.  The  word  pound, 
as  a  money-name,  thus  becomes  differentiated  from  the  same 
word  as  a  weight-name.  ''^  (8)  The  debasing  of  nioney  carried 
on  for  centuries  by  kings  and  princes  to  such  an  extent  that,  of 
the  original  weights  of  the  coins,  nothing  in  fact  remained  but 
the  names. 

These  historical  causes  convert  the  separation  of  the  money- 
name  from  the  weight-name  into  an  established  habit  with  the 
community.  Since  the  standard  of  money  is  on  the  one  hand 
purely  conventional,  and  must  on  the  other  hand  find  general 
acceptance,  it  is  in  the  end  regulated  by  law.  A  given  weight 
of  one  of  the  precious  metals,  an  ounce  of  gold,  for  instance, 
becomes  officially  divided  into  aliquot  parts,  with  legally 
bestowed  names,  such  as  pound,  dollar,  &c.  These  aliquot 
parts,  which  thenceforth  serve  as  units  of  money,  are  then  sub- 
divided into  other  aliquot  parts  with  legal  names,  such  as 
shilling,  penny,  &c.  ^  But,  both  before  and  after  these 
divisions  are  made,  a  definite  weight  of  metal  is  the  standard 
of  metallic  money.  The  sole  alteration  consists  in  the  sub- 
division and  denomination. 

1  Moreover,  it  has  not  general  historical  validity. 

2  It  is  thus  that  the  pound  sterling  in  English  denotes  less  than  one-third  of  its 
original  weight ;  the  pound  Scot,  before  the  union,  only  l-36th ;  the  French  livre, 
l-74th ;  the  Spanish  niaravedi,  less  than  1-lOOOth ;  and  the  Portuguese  rei  a  still 
smaller  fraction. 

3  "  Le  monete  le  quali  oggi  sono  ideali  sono  le  piu  antiche  d'ogni  nazione,  e  tutte 
furono  un  tempo  reali,  e  perche  erano  reali  con  esse  si  contava."  (Galiani:  Delia 
moneta,  1.  c,  p.  153.) 

4  David  Urquhart  remarks  in  his  "Familiar  Words  "  on  the  monstrosity  (!)  that 
now-a-days  a  pound  (sterling),  which  is  the  unit  of  the  English  standard  of  money,  is 
equal  to  about  a  quarter  of  an  ounce  of  gold.  "This  is  falsifying  a  measure,  not 
establishing  a  standard."  He  sees  in  this  "false  denomination"  of  the  weight  of 
gold,  as  in  everything  else,  the  falsifying  hand  of  civilisation. 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.      J2> 

The  prices,  or  quantities  of  gold,  into  which  the  values  of 
commodities  are  ideally  changed,  are  therefore  now  expressed 
in  the  names  of  coins,  or  in  the  legally  valid  names  of  the  sub- 
divisions of  the  gold  standard.  Hence,  instead  of  saying :  A 
quarter  of  wheat  is  worth  an  ounce  of  gold ;  we  say,  it  is  worth 
£3  17s.  lOJd.  In  this  way  commodities  express  by  their  prices 
how  much  they  are  worth,  and  money  serves  as  money  of 
account  whenever  it  is  a  question  of  fixing  the  value  of  an 
article  in  its  money-form.  ^ 

The  name  of  a  thing  is  something  distinct  from  the  qualities 
of  that  thing.  I  know  nothing  of  a  man,  by  knowing  that  his 
name  is  Jacob.  In  the  same  way  with  regard  to  money,  every 
trace  of  a  value-relation  disappears  in  the  names  pound,  dollar, 
franc,  ducat,  &c.  The  confusion  caused  by  attributing  a  hidden 
meaning  to  these  cabalistic  signs  is  all  the  greater,  because 
these  money-names  express  both  the  values  of  commodities, 
and,  at  the  same  time,  aliquot  parts  of  the  weight  of  the  metal 
that  is  the  standard  of  money.  ^  On  the  other  hand,  it  is 
absolutely  necessary  that  value,  in  order  that  it  may  be  distin- 
guished from  the  varied  bodily  forms  of  commodities,  should 
assume  this  material  and  unmeaning,  but,  at  the  same  time, 
purely  social  form.  ^ 

1  When  Anacharsis  was  asked  for  what  purposes  the  Greeks  used  money,  he  replied, 
'/For  reckoning."    (Athen.  Deipn.  1.  iv.  49  v.  2.  ed  Schweighauser,  1802.) 

2  "  Owing  to  the  fact  that  money,  when  serving  as  the  standard  of  price,  appears 
under  the  same  reckoning  names  as  do  the  prices  of  commodities,  and  that  therefore 
the  sum  of  £3  17s.  lO^d.  may  signify  on  the  one  hand  an  ounce  weight  of  gold,  and 
ovi  the  other,  the  value  of  a  ton  of  iron,  this  reckoning  name  of  money  has  been 
called  its  mint-price.  Hence  there  sprang  up  the  extraordinary  notion,  that  the 
value  of  gold  is  estimated  in  its  own  material,  and  that,  in  contra-distinction  to  all 
other  commodities,  its  price  is  fixed  by  the  State.  It  was  erroneously  thought  that 
the  giving  of  reckoning  names  to  definite  weights  of  gold,  is  the  same  thing  as  fixing 
the  value  of  those  weights. "    (Karl  Marx.  1.  c. ,  p.  52. ) 

3  See  "  Theorien  von  der  Masseinheit  des  Geldes  "  in  *'  Zur  Kritik  der  Pol.  Oekon. 
&c.,"p.  53,  seq.  The  fantastic  notions  about  raising  or  lowering  the  mint-price  of 
money  by  transferring  to  greater  or  smaller  weights  of  gold  or  silver  the  names  already 
legally  appropriated  to  fixed  weights  of  those  metals  ;  such  notions,  at  least  in  those 
cases  in  which  they  aim,  not  at  clumsy  financial  operations  against  creditors,  both 
jDublic  and  private,  but  at  economical  quack  remedies,  have  been  so  exhaustively 
treated  by  Wm.  Petty  in  his  "  Quantulumcunque  concerning  money:  To  the  Lord 
Marquis  of  Halifax,  1G82,"  that  even  his  immediate  followers,  Sir  Dudley  North  and 
John  Locke,  not  to  mention  later  ones,  could  only  dilute  him.  "  If  the  wealth  of  a 
nation,"  he  remarks,  "could  be  decupled  by  a  proclamation,  it  were  strange  that 
such  proclamations  have  not  long  since  been  made  by  our  Governors."    (1.  c,  p.  36.) 


74 


Capitalist  Production. 


r 

I' 

■J\. 


Price  is  the  money-name  of  the  labour  realised  in  a  commo- 
dity. Hence  the  expression  of  the  equivalence  of  a  commodity 
with  the  sum  of  money  constituting  its  price,  is  a  tautology/ 
just  as  in  general  the  expression  of  the  relative  value  of  a 
commodity  is  a  statement  of  the  equivalence  of  two  commodities. 
But  although  price,  being  the  exponent  of  the  magnitude  of  a 
commodity's  value,  is  the  exponent  of  its  exchange-ratio  with 
money,  it  does  not  follow  that  the  exponent  of  this  exchange- 
ratio  IS  necessarily  the  exponent  of  the  magnitude  of  the  com- 
modity's value.  Suppose  two  equal  quantities  of  socially 
necessary  labour  to  be  respectively  represented  by  1  quarter 
of  wheat  and  £2  (nearly  J  oz.  of  gold),  £2  is  the  expression  in 
money  of  the  magnitude  of  the  value  of  the  quarter  of  wheat, 
or  is  its  price.  If  now  circumstances  allow  of  this  price  being 
raised  to  £3,  or  compel  it  to  be  reduced  to  £1,  then  although 
£1  and  £3  may  be  too  small  or  too  great  properly  to  express 
the  magnitude  of  the  wheat's  value,  nevertheless  they  are  its 
prices,  for  they  are,  in  the  first  place,  the  form  under  which  its 
value  appears,  i.e.,  money ;  and  in  the  second  place,  the  ex- 
ponents of  its  exchange-ratio  with  money.  If  the  conditions 
of  production,  in  other  words,  if  the  productive  power  of  labour 
remain  constant,  the  same  amount  of  social  labour-time  must, 
both  before  and  after  the  change  in  price,  be  expended  in  the 
reproduction  of  a  quarter  of  wheat.  This  circumstance  de-  j 
pends,  neither  on  the  will  of  the  wheat  producer,  nor  on  that  / 
of  the  owners  of  other  commodities. 

Magnitude  of  value  expresses  a  relation  of  social  production, 
it  expresses  the  connection  that  necessarily  exists  between  a 
certain  article  and  the  portion  of  the  total  labour-time  of  society 
required  to  produce  it.  As  soon  as  magnitude  of  value  is  con- 
verted into  price,  the  above  necessary  relation  takes  the  shape 
of  a  more  or  less  accidental  exchange-ratio  between  a  single 
commodity  and  another,  the  money-commodity.  But  this  ex- 
change-ratio may  express  either  the  real  magnitude  of  that 
commodity's  value,  or  the  quantity  of  gold  deviating  from  that 
value,  for  which,  according  to  circumstances,  it  may  be  parted 

1  "Ou  bien,  il  faut  consentir  ^  dire  qn'une  valeur  d'un  million  en  argent  vaut  plus 
qu'une  valeur  egale  en  marcliandises  "  (Le  Trosne  1.  c.  p.  919),  which  amounts  to 
saying  "  qu'une  valeur  vaut  plus  qu'une  valeur  egale." 


Money y  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,       75, 

with.  The  possibility,  therefore,  of  quantitative  incongruity 
between  price  and  magnitude  of  value,  or  the  deviation  of  the 
former  from  the  latter,  is  inherent  in  the  price-form  itself. 
This  is  no  defect,  but,  on  the  contrary,  admirably  adapts  the 
price-form  to  a  mode  of  production  whose  inherent  laws  impose 
themselves  only  as  the  mean  of  apparently  lawless  irregulari-  / 
ties  that  compensate  one  another. 

The  price-form,  however,  is  not  only  compatible  with  the 
possibilit}^  of  a  quantitative  incongruity  between  magnitude 
of  value  and  price,  i.e.^  between  the  former  and  its  expression 
in  money,  but  it  may  also  conceal  a  qualitative  inconsistency,  so 
much  so,  that,  although  money  is  nothing  but  the  value -form  of    v3 
commodities,  price  ceases  altogether  to  express  value.     Objects 
that  in  themselves  are  no  commodities,  such  as  conscience,  honour, 
&c.,  are  capable  of  being  offered  for  sale  by  their  holders,  and 
of  thus  acquiring,  through  their  price,  the  form  of  commodities. 
Hence  an  object  may  have  a  price  without  having  value.     The 
price  in  that  case  is  imaginary,  like  certain  quantities  in  mathe-        ^    ^ 
matics.     On  the  other  hand,  the  imaginary  price-form  may     O 
sometimes  conceal  either  a  direct  or  indirect  real  value-relation; 
for  instance,  the  price  of  uncultivated  land,  which  is  without 
value,  because  no  human  labour  has  been  incorporated  in  it. 

Price,  like  relative  value  in  general,  expresses  the  value  of 
a  commodity  {e.g.,  a  ton  of  iron),  by  stating  that  a  given  quan- 
tity of  the  equivalent  {e.g.^  an  ounce  of  gold),  is  directly  ex- 
changeable for  iron.  But  it  by  no  means  states  the  converse,  ' 
that  iron  is  directly  exchangeable  for  gold.  In  order,  there- 
fore, that  a  commodity  may  in  practice  act  effectively  as  ex- 
change value,  it  must  quit  its  bodily  shape,  must  transform  it- 
self from  mere  imaginary  into  real  gold,  although  to  the  commo-  • 
dity  such  transubstantiation  may  be  more  difficult  than  to  the 
Hegelian  "  concept,"  the  transition  from  "  necessity  "  to  "  free- 
dom," or  to  a  lobster  the  casting  of  his  shell,  or  to  Saint  Jerome 
the  putting  off  of  the  old  Adam.^     Though  a  commodity  may, 

^  Jerome  had  to  wrestle  hard,  not  only  in  his  youth  with  the  bodily  flesh,  as  is 
shown  by  his  fight  in  the  desert  with  the  handsome  women  of  his  imagination,  but 
also  in  his  old  age  with  the  spiritual  flesh.  *'  I  thought,"  he  says,  "I  was  in  the 
spirit  before  the  Judge  of  the  Universe."  "Who  art  thou ?  "  asked  a  voice.  "  I  am 
a  Christian."  "Thou  liest,"  thundered  back  the  great  Judge,  "thou  art  nought  but 
a  Ciceronian." 


76  Capitalist  Production. 

side  by  side  with  its  actual  form  (iron,  for  instance),  take  in 
our  imagination  the  form  of  gold,  yet  it  cannot  at  one  and  the 
same  time  actually  be  both  iron  and  gold.  To  fix  its  price,  it 
sulfices  to  equate  it  to  gold  in  imagination.  But  to  enable  it  to 
render  to  its  owner  the  service  of  a  universal  equivalent,  it 
must  be  actually  replaced  by  gold.  If  the  owner  of  the  iron 
were  to  go  to  the  owner  of  some  other  commodity  offered  for 
exchange,  and  were  to  refer  him  to  the  price  of  the  iron  as 
proof  that  it  was  already  money,  he  would  get  the  same 
answer  as  St.  Peter  gave  in  heaven  to  Dante,  when  the  latter 
recited  the  creed — 

"  Assai  bene  e  trascorsa 

D'esta  moneta  gik  la  lega  e'l  peso, 

Ma  dimmi  se  tu  Thai  nella  tua  borsa. " 

A  price  therefore  implies  both  that  a  commodity  is  exchange- 
able for  money,  and  also  that  it  must  be  so  exchanged.  On 
the  other  hand,  gold  serves  as  an  ideal  measure  of  value,  only 
because  it  has  already,  in  the  process  of  exchange,  established 
itself  as  the  money-commodity.  Under  the  ideal  measure  of 
values  there  lurks  the  hard  cash. 

SECTION   2. — THE   MEDIUM   OF   CIRCULATION. 

a.  The  Metamorphosis  of  Commodities. 

"We  saw  in  a  former  chapter  that  the  exchange  of  commodi- 
ties implies  contradictory  and  mutually  exclusive  conditions. 
The  differentiation  of  commodities  into  commodities  and  money 
does  not  sweep  away  these  inconsistencies,  but  developes 
a  modus  vivendi,  a  form  in  which  they  can  exist  side  by  side. 
This  is  generally  the  way  in  which  real  contradictions  are 
reconciled.  For  instance,  it  is  a  contradiction  to  depict  one 
body  as  constantly  falling  towards  another,  and  as,  at  the  same 
time,  constantly  flying  away  from  it.  The  ellipse  is  a  form  of 
motion  which,  while  allowing  this  contradiction  to  go  on,  at  the 
same  time  reconciles  it. 

In  so  far  as  exchange  is  a  process,  by  which  commodities  are 
transferred  from  hands  in  which  they  are  non-use- values,  to 
hands  in  which  they  become  use- values,  it  is  a  social  circula- 
tion of  matter.     The  product  of  one  form  of  useful  labour 


Money,  or  the  Ciradation  of  Com7nodities.       yy 

replaces  that  of  another.  When  once  a  commodity  has  found 
a  resting-place,  where  it  can  serve  as  a  use-value,  it  falls  out 
of  the  sphere  of  exchange  into  that  of  consumption.  But  the 
former  sphere  alone  interests  us  at  present.  We  have,  there- 
fore, now  to  consider  exchange  from  a  formal  point  of  view ;  to 
investigate  the  change  of  form  or  metamorphosis  of  commodi- 
ties which  effectuates  the  social  circulation  of  matter. 

The  comprehension  of  this  change  of  form  is,  as  a  rule,  very 
imperfect.  The  cause  of  this  imperfection  is,  apart  from  indis- 
tinct notions  of  value  itself,  that  every  change  of  form  in  a 
commodity  results  from  the  exchange  of  two  commodities,  an 
ordinary  one  and  the  money-commodity.  If  we  keep  in  view  the 
material  fact  alone  thata  commodity  has  been  exchanged  for  gold^ 
we  overlook  the  very  thing  that  we  ought  to  observe — namely, 
what  has  happened  to  the  form  of  the  commodity.  We  overlook 
the  facts  that  gold,  when  a  mere  commodity,  is  not  money,  and 
that  when  other  commodities  express  their  prices  in  gold,  this 
gold  is  but  the  money-form  of  those  commodities  themselves. 

Commodities,  first  of  all,  enter  into  the  process  of  exchange 
just  as  they  are.  The  process  then  differentiates  them  into 
commodities  and  money,  and  thus  produces  an  external  oppo- 
sition corresponding  to  the  internal  opposition  inherent  in 
them,  as  being  at  once  use-values  and  values.  Commodities  as 
use-values  now  stand  opposed  to  money  as  exchange  value. 
On  the  other  hand,  both  opposing  sides  are  commodities, 
unities  of  use- value  and  value.  But  this  unity  of  differences^ 
manifests  itself  at  two  opposite  poles,  and  at  each  pole  in  an 
opposite  way.  Being  poles  they  are  as  necessarily  opposite  as 
they  are  connected.  On  the  one  side  of  the  equation  we  have 
an  ordinary  commodity,  which  is  in  reality  a  use-value.  Its 
value  is  expressed  only  ideally  in  its  price,  by  which  it  is 
equated  to  its  opponent,  the  gold,  as  to  the  real  embodiment 
of  its  value.  On  the  other  hand,  the  gold,  in  its  metallic 
reality,  ranks  as  the  embodiment  of  value,  as  money.  Gold, 
as  gold,  is  exchange  value  itself.  As  to  its  use- value,  that  has 
only  an  ideal  existence,  represented  by  the  series  of  expres- 
sions of  relative  value  in  which  it  stands  face  to  face  with  all 
other  commodities,  the  sum  of  whose  uses  makes  up  the  sum 


78  Capitalist  Production, 

of  the  various  uses  of  gold.  These  antagonistic  forms  of  com- 
modities are  the  real  forms  in  which  the  process  of  their 
exchange  moves  and  takes  place. 

Let  us  now  accompany  the  owner  of  some  commodity — say, 
our  old  friend  the  weaver  of  linen — to  the  scene  of  action,  the 
market.  His  20  yards  of  linen  has  a  definite  price,  £2.  He 
exchanges  it  for  the  £2,  and  then,  like  a  man  of  the  good  old 
stamp  that  he  is,  he  parts  with  the  £2  for  a  family  Bible  of  the 
same  price.  The  linen,  which  in  his  eyes  is  a  mere  commodity, 
a  depository  of  value,  he  alienates  in  exchange  for  gold,  which 
is  the  linen's  value-form,  and  this  form  he  again  parts  with  for 
another  commodity,  the  Bible,  which  is  destined  to  enter  his 
house  as  an  object  of  utility  and  of  edification  to  its  inmates. 
The  exchange  becomes  an  accomplished  fact  by  two  metamor- 
phoses of  opposite  yet  supplementary  character — the  conversion 
of  the  commodity  into  money,  and  the  re-conversion  of  the 
money  into  a  commodity.^  The  two  phases  of  this  metamor- 
phosis are  both  of  them  distinct  transactions  of  the  weaver — 
selling,  or  the  exchange  of  the  commodity  for  money ;  buying, 
or  the  exchange  of  the  money  for  a  commodity  ;  and,  the  unity 
of  the  two  acts,  selling  in  order  to  buy. 

The  result  of  the  whole  transaction,  as  regards  the  weaver, 
is  this,  that  instead  of  being  in  possession  of  the  linen,  he  now 
has  the  Bible  ;  instead  of  his  original  commodity,  he  now. 
possesses  another  of  the  same  value  but  of  difierent  utility. 
In  like  manner  he  procures  his  other  means  of  subsistence  and 
means  of  production.  From  his  point  of  view,  the  whole  process 
effectuates  nothing  more  than  the  exchange  of  the  product  of 
his  labour  for  the  product  of  some  one  else's,  nothing  more  than 
an  exchange  of  products. 

The  exchange  of  commodities  is  therefore  accompanied  by 
the  followino^  chancres  in  their  form. 

Commodity — Money — Commodity. 
C M C. 

The  result  of  the  whole  process  is,  so  far  as  concerns  the 

*    "  Ix  S^  TflO -yTvpos   dvTOtfjCiifiiff^oci   'ffa.itru^   (pyja-lv  o  'HptxxXitrot:,  xa,l    <^up 

^•rdvTaiv,  wff-xnp  ^pvffov  ^p'/i[M>t,ro!.  xa)  ^pn[jt.a.Tuv  ;t;pi'a*oj."  (F.  Lassalle :  Die  Philosophie 
Herakleitos  des  Dunkeln.  Berlin,  1845.  Vol.  I,  p.  222.)  Lassalle,  in  his  note  on 
this  passage,  p.  224,  n.  3,  erroneously  makes  gold  a  mere  symbol  of  value. 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,      79 

objects  themselves,  C — C,  the  exchange  of  one  commodity  for 
another,  the  circulation  of  materialised  social  labour.  When 
this  result  is  attained,  the  process  is  at  an  end. 

G — M.     First  metamorphosis,  or  sale. 

The  leap  taken  by  value  from  the  body  of  the  commodity, 
into  the  body  of  the  gold,  is,  as  I  have  elsewhere  called  it,  the 
salto  mortale  of  the  commodity.  If  it  falls  short,  then,  although 
the  commodity  itself  is  not  harmed,  its  owner  decidedly  is. 
The  social  division  of  labour  causes  his  labour  to  be  as  one-sided 
as  his  wants  are  many-sided.  This  is  precisely  the  reason  why 
tne  product  of  his  labour  serves  him  solely  as  exchange  value. 
But  it  cannot  acquire  the  properties  of  a  socially  recognised 
universal  equivalent,  except  by  being  converted  into  money. 
That  money,  however,  is  in  some  one  else's  pocket.  In  order  to 
entice  the  money  out  of  that  pocket,  our  friend's  commodity 
must,  above  all  things,  be  a  use-value  to  the  owner  of  the 
money.  For  this,  it  is  necessary  that  the  labour  expended  upon 
it,  be  of  a  kind  that  is  socially  useful,  of  a  kind  that  constitutes 
a  branch  of  the  social  division  of  labour.  But  division  of  labour 
is  a  system  of  production  which  has  grown  up  spontaneously 
and  continues  to  grow  behind  the  backs  of  the  producers.  The 
commodity  to  be  exchanged  may  possibly  be  the  product  of 
some  new  kind  of  labour,  that  pretends  to  satisfy  newly  arisen 
requirements,  or  even  to  give  rise  itself  to  new  requirements.  A 
particular  operation,  though  yesterday,  perhaps,  forming  one  out 
of  the  many  operations  conducted  by  one  producer  in  creating  a 
given  commodity,  may  to-day  separate  itself  from  this  connection, 
may  establish  itself  as  an  independent  branch  of  labour  and  send 
its  incomplete  product  to  market  as  an  independent  commodity. 
The  circumstances  may  or  may  not  be  ripe  for  such  a  separation. 
To-day  the  product  satisfies  asocial  want.  To-morrow  the  article 
may,  either  altogether  or  partially,  be  superseded  by  some  other 
appropriate  product.  Moreover,  although  our  weaver's  labour 
may  be  a  recognised  branch  of  the  social  division  of  labour, 
yet  that  fact  is  by  no  means  sufficient  to  guarantee  the  utility 
of  his  20  yards  of  linen.  If  the  community's  want  of  linen,  and 
such  a  want  has  a  limit  like  every  other  want,  should  already 


8o  Capitalist  Production, 

be  saturated  by  the  products  of  rival  weavers,  our  friend's 
product  is  superfluous,  redundant,  and  consequently  useless. 
Although  people  do  not  look  a  gift-horse  in  the  mouth,  our 
friend  does  not  frequent  the  market  for  the  purpose  of  making 
presents.  But  suppose  his  product  turn  out  a  real  use-value, 
and  thereby  attracts  money  ?  The  question  arises,  how  much 
will  it  attract  ?  No  doubt  the  answer  is  already  anticipated 
in  the  price  of  the  article,  in  the  exponent  of  the  magnitude  of 
its  value.  We  leave  out  of  consideration  here  any  accidental 
miscalculation  of  value  by  our  friend,  a  mistake  that  is  soon 
rectified  in  the  market.  We  suppose  him  to  have  spent  on  his 
product  only  that  amount  of  labour- time  that  is  on  an  average 
socially  necessary.  The  price  then,  is  merely  the  money-name 
of  the  quantity  of  social  labour  realised  in  his  commodity.  But 
without  the  leave,  and  behind  the  back,  of  our  weaver,  the 
old  fashioned  mode  of  weaving  undergoes  a  change.  The  labour- 
time  that  yesterday  was  without  doubt  socially  necessary  to 
the  production  of  a  yard  of  linen,  ceases  to  be  so  to-day,  a  fact 
which  the  owner  of  the  money  is  only  too  eager  to  prove  from 
the  prices  quoted  by  our  friend's  competitors.  Unluckily  for 
him,  weavers  are  not  few  and  far  between.  Lastly,  suppose 
that  every  piece  of  linen  in  the  market  contains  no  more  labour- 
time  than  is  socially  necessary.  In  spite  of  this,  all  these  pieces 
taken  as  a  whole,  may  have  had  superfluous  labour-time  spent 
upon  them.  If  the  market  cannot  stomach  the  whole  quantity 
at  the  normal  price  of  2  shillings  a  yard,  this  proves  that  too 
great  a  portion  of  the  total  labour  of  the  community  has  been 
expended  in  the  form  of  weaving.  The  efiect  is  the  same  as  if 
each  individual  weaver  had  expended  more  labour- time  upon 
his  particular  product  than  is  socially  necessar}^  Here  we  may 
say,  with  the  German  proverb  :  caught  together,  hung  together. 
All  the  linen  in  the  market  counts  but  as  one  article  of  commerce, 
of  which  each  piece  is  only  an  aliquot  part.  And  as  a  matter 
of  fact,  the  value  also  of  each  single  yard  is  but  the  materialised 
form  of  the  same  definite  and  socially  fixed  quantity  of  homo- 
geneous human  labour. 

We  see  then,  commodities  are  in  love  with  money,  but  "  the 
course  of  true  love  never  did  run  smooth."     The  quantitative 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,       8i 

division  of  labour  is  brought  about  in  exactly  the  same  spon- 
taneous and  accidental  manner  as  its  qualitative  division.  The 
owners  of  commodities  therefore  find  out,  that  the  same  divi- 
sion of  labour  that  turns  them  into  independent  private 
producers,  also  frees  the  social  process  of  production  and  the 
relations  of  the  individual  producers  to  each  other  within  that 
process,  from  all  dependence  on  the  will  of  those  producers, 
and  that  the  seeming  mutual  independence  of  the  individuals  is 
supplemented  by  a  system  ot  general  and  mutual  dependence 
through  or  by  means  of  the  products. 

The  division  of  labour  converts  the  product  of  labour  into  a 
commodity,  and  thereby  makes  necessary  its  further  conversion 
into  money.  At  the  same  time  it  also  makes  the  accomplish- 
ment of  this  trans-substantiation  quite  accidental.  Here,  how- 
ever, we  are  only  concerned  with  the  phenomenon  in  its 
integrity,  and  we  therefore  assume  its  progress  to  be  normal. 
Moreover,  if  the  conversion  take  place  at  all,  that  is,  if  the 
commodity  be  not  absolutely  unsaleable,  its  metamorphosis 
does  take  place  althougli  the  price  realised  may  be  abnormally 
above  or  below  the  value. 

The  seller  has  his  commodity  replaced  by  gold,  the  buyer 
has  his  gold  replaced  by  a  commodity.  The  fact  which  here 
stares  us  in  the  face  is,  that  a  commodity  and  gold,  20  yards 
of  linen  and  £2,  have  changed  hands  and  places,  in  other  words, 
that  they  have  been  exchanged.  But  for  what  is  the  com- 
modity exchanged?  For  the  shape  assumed  by  its  own  value, 
for  the  universal  equivalent.  And  for  what  is  the  gold 
exchanged  ?  For  a  particular  form  of  its  own  use-value. 
Why  does  gold  take  the  form  of  money  face  to  face  with  the 
linen  ?  Because  the  linen's  price  of  £2,  its  denomination  in 
money,  has  already  equated  the  linen  to  gold  in  its  character 
of  money.  A  commodity  strips  off  its  original  commodity-form 
on  being  alienated,  i.e.,  on  the  instant  its  use-value  actually 
attracts  the  gold,  that  before  existed  only  ideally  in  its  price. 
The  realisation  of  a  commodity's  price,  or  of  its  ideal  value- 
form,  is  therefore  at  the  same  time  the  realisation  of  the  ideal 
use-value  of  money ;  the  conversion  of  a  commodity  into 
money,  is  the  simultaneous  conversion  of  money  into  a  com- 


82  Capitalist  Production, 

modity.  The  apparently  single  process  is  in  reality  a  double 
one.  From  the  pole  of  the  commodity  owner  it  is  a  sale,  from 
the  opposite  pole  of  the  money  owner,  it  is  a  purchase.  In 
other  words,  a  sale  is  a  purchase,  C — M  is  also  M — C.^ 

Up  to  this  point  we  have  considered  men  in  only  one  econo- 
mical capacity,  that  of  owners  of  commodities,  a  capacity  in 
which  they  appropriate  the  produce  of  the  labour  of  others,  by 
alienating  that  of  their  own  labour.  Hence,  for  one  commodity 
owner  to  meet  with  another  who  has  money,  it  is  necessary, 
either,  that  the  product  of  the  labour  of  the  latter  person,  the 
buyer,  should  be  in  itself  money,  should  be  gold,  the  material 
of  which  money  consists,  or  that  his  product  should  already 
have  changed  its  skin  and  have  stripped  off  its  original  form 
of  a  useful  object.  In  order  that  it  may  play  the  part  of 
money,  gold  must  of  course  enter  the  market  at  some  point  or 
other.  This  point  is  to  be  found  at  the  source  of  production 
of  the  metal,  at  which  place  gold  is  bartered,  as  the  immediate 
product  of  labour,  for  some  other  product  of  equal  value. 
From  that  moment  it  always  represents  the  realised  price  of 
some  commodity.^  Apart  from  its  exchange  for  other  com- 
modities at  the  source  of  its  production,  gold,  in  whose-so-ever 
hands  it  may  be,  is  the  transformed  shape  of  some  commodity 
alienated  by  its  owner;  it  is  the  product  of  a  sale  or  of  the  first 
metamorphosis  C — M.^  Gold,  as  we  saw,  became  ideal  money, 
or  a  measure  of  values,  in  consequence  of  all  commodities 
measuring  their  values  by  it,  and  thus  contrasting  it  ideally 
with  their  natural  shape  as  useful  objects,  and  making  it  the 
shape  of  their  value.  It  became  real  money,  by  the  general 
alienation  of  commodities,  by  actually  changing  places  with  their 
natural  forms  as  useful  objects,  and  thus  becoming  in  reality 
the  embodiment  of  their  values.  When  they  assume  this 
money-shape,  commodities  strip  off  every  trace  of  their  natural 
use-value,  and  of  the  particular  kind  of  labour  to  which  they 

1  "Toute  vente  est  achat."  (Dr.  Quesnay  :  "Dialogues  sur  le  Commerce  et  les 
Travaux  ties  Artisans.'.'  Physiocrates  ed.  Daire  I.  Partie,  Paris,  184G,  j).  170),  or  as 
■Quesnay  in  his  "  Maximes  generales  "  puts  it,  "  Vendre  est  acheter." 

2  "  Le  prix  d'une  marchandise  ne  isouvant  etre  paye  que  par  le  i^rix  d'une  autre  mar- 
•chandise."  (Mercier  de  la  Riviere  :  *'  L'Ordre  naturel  et  essentiel  des  societes  poli- 
tiques."    Physiocrates,  ed.  Daire  II.  Partie,  p.  554). 

3  "Pour  avoir  cet  argent,  il  faut  avoir  vendu,"  1.  c,  p.  543. 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,       8 


J 


owe  their  creation,  in  order  to  transform  themselves  into  the 
uniform,  socially  recognised  incarnation  of  homogeneous  human 
labour.  We  cannot  tell  from  the  mere  look  of  a  piece  of 
money,  for  what  particular  commodity  it  has  been  exchanged. 
Under  their  money-form  all  commodities  look  alike.  Hence, 
money  may  be  dirt,  although  dirt  is  not  money.  We  will 
assume  tliat  the  two  gold  pieces,  in  consideration  of  which  our 
weaver  has  parted  with  his  linen,  are  the  metamorphosed  shape 
of  a  quarter  of  wheat.  The  sale  of  the  linen,  C — M,  is  at  the 
same  time  its  purchase,  M — C.  But  the  sale  is  the  first  act  of 
a  process  that  ends  with  a  transaction  of  an  opposite  nature, 
namely,  the  purchase  of  a  Bible ;  the  purchase  of  the  linen,  on 
the  other  hand,  ends  a  movement  that  began  with  a  transac- 
tion of  an  opposite  nature,  namely,  with  the  sale  of  the  wheat. 
C — M  (linen — money),  which  is  the  first  phase  of  C — M — C 
(linen — money — Bible),  is  also  M — C  (money — linen),  the  last 
])hase  of  another  movement  C — M — C  (wheat — money — linen). 
The  first  metamorphosis  of  one  commodity,  its  transforma- 
tion from  a  commodity  into  money,  is  therefore  also  invariably 
the  second  metamorphosis  of  some  other  commodity,  the  re- 
transformation  of  the  latter  from  money  into  a  commodity.^ 

M — (7,   or  jpwrchase.      The   second  a7id  concluding   metamor- 
phosis of  a  comnm^odity. 

Because  money  is  the  metamorphosed  shape  of  all  other 
commodities,  the  result  of  their  general  alienation,  for  this 
reason  it  is  alienable  itself  without  restriction  or  condition. 
It  reads  all  prices  backwards,  and  thus,  so  to  say,  depicts  itself 
in  the  bodies  of  all  other  commodities,  which  offer  to  it  the 
material  for  the  realisation  of  its  own  use-value.  At  the  same 
time  the  prices,  wooing  glances  cast  at  money  by  commodities, 
define  the  limits  of  its  convertibility,  by  pointing  to  its  quantity. 
Since  every  commodity,  on  becoming  money,  disappears  as  a 
commodity,  it  is  impossible  to  tell  from  the  money  itself,  how 
it  got  into  the  hands  of  its  possessor,  or  what  article  has  been 
changed  into  it.     Non  olet,  from  whatever  source  it  may  come. 

1  As  before  remarked,  the  actual  producer  of  gold  or  silver  forms  an  exception.     He 
exchanges  his  product  directly  for  another  commodity,  without  having  first  sold  it. 


84  Capitalist  Production. 

Representing  on  the  one  hand  a  sold  commodity,  it  represents 
on  the  other  a  commodity  to  be  bought/ 

M — C,  a  purchase,  is,  at  the  same  time,  C — M,  a  sale  ;  the  con- 
chiding  metamorphosis  of  one  commodity  is  the  first  metamor- 
phosis of  another.  With  regard  to  our  weaver,  the  life  of  his 
commodity  ends  with  the  Bible,  into  which  he  has  reconverted 
his  £2.  But  suppose  the  seller  of  the  Bible  turns  the  £2  set 
free  by  the  weaver  into  brandy.  M — 0,  the  concluding  phase 
of  C — M — C  (linen,  money,  Bible),  is  also  C — M,  the  first  phase 
of  C — M — C  (Bible,  money,  brandy).  The  producer  of  a  par- 
ticular commodity  has  that  one  article  alone  to  offer ;  this  he 
sells  very  often  in  large  quantities,  but  his  many  and  various 
wants  compel  him  to  split  up  the  price  realised,  the  sum  of 
money  set  free,  into  numerous  purchases.  Hence  a  sale  leads 
to  many  purchases  of  various  articles.  The  concluding  meta- 
morphosis of  a  commodity  thus  constitutes  an  aggregation  of 
first  metamorphoses  of  various  other  commodities. 

If  we  now  consider  the  completed  metamorphosis  of  a  com- 
modity, as  a  whole,  it  appears  in  the  first  place,  that  it  is  made 
up  of  two  opposite  and  complementary  movements,  C — M  and 
M — C.  These  two  antithetical  transmutations  of  a  commodity 
are  brought  about  by  two  antithetical  social  acts  on  the  pait 
of  the  owner,  and  these  acts  in  their  turn  stamp  the  character 
of  the  economical  parts  played  by  him.  As  the  person  who 
makes  a  sale,  he  is  a  seller ;  as  the  person  who  makes  a  pur- 
chase, he  is  a  buyer.  But  just  as,  upon  every  such  transmu- 
tation of  a  commodity,  its  two  forms,  commodity-form  and 
money-form,  exist  simultaneously  but  at  opposite  poles,  so 
every  seller  has  a  buyer  opposed  to  him,  and  every  buyer  a 
seller.  While  one  particular  commodity  is  going  through  its 
two  transmutations  in  succession,  from  a  commodity  into 
money  and  from  money  into  another  commodity,  the  owner  of 
the  commodity  changes  in  succession  his  part  from  that  of 
seller  to  that  of  buyer.  These  characters  of  seller  and  buyer 
are  therefore  not  permanent,  but  attach  themselves  in  turns  to 
the  various  persons  engaged  in  the  circulation  of  commodities. 

1  "  Si  I'argent  represente,  dans  nos  mains,  les  choses  que  nous  pouvons  desirer 
d'acheter,  il  y  represente  aussi  les  choses  que  nous  avons  vendues  pour  cet  ardent  " 
(Mercier  de  la  Rividre  1.  c.  p.  586.) 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,      85 

The  complete  metamorphosis  of  a  commodity,  in  its  simjjlest 
form,  implies  four  extremes,  and  three  dramatis  personse. 
First,  a  commodity  comes  face  to  face  with  money ;  the  latter 
is  the  form  taken  by  the  value  of  the  former,  and  exists  in  al 
its  hard  reality,  in  the  pocket  of  the  buyer.  A  commodity- 
owner  is  thus  brought  into  contact  with  a  possessor  of  money. 
So  soon,  now,  as  the  commodity  has  been  changed  into 
money,  the  money  becomes  its  transient  equivalent- form,  the 
use -value  of  which  equivalent-form  is  to  be  found  in  the 
bodies  of  other  commodities.  Money,  the  final  term  of  the 
first  transmutation,  is  at  the  same  time  the  starting  point  for 
the  second.  The  person  who  is  a  seller  in  the  first  transac- 
tion thus  becomes  a  buyer  in  the  second,  in  which  a  third 
commodity- owner  appears  on  the  scene  as  a  seller.^ 

The  two  phases,  each  inverse  to  the  other,  that  make  up  the 
metamorphosis  of  a  commodity  constitute  together  a  circular 
movement,  a  circuit:  commodity-form,  stripping  off  of  this 
form,  and  return  to  the  commodity-form.  No  doubt,  tlie  com- 
modity appears  here  under  two  different  aspects.  At  the  start- 
ing point  it  is  not  a  use- value  to  its  owner ;  at  the  finishing 
point  it  is.  So,  too,  the  money  appears  in  the  first  phase  as  a 
solid  crystal  of  value,  a  crystal  into  which  the  commodity 
eagerly  solidifies,  and  in  the  second,  dissolves  into  the  mere 
transient  equivalent-form  destined  to  be  replaced  by  a  use- 
value. 

The  two  metamorphoses  constituting  the  circuit  are  at  the 
same  time  two  inverse  partial  metamorphoses  of  two  otlier 
commodities.  One  and  the  same  commodity,  the  linen,  opens  the 
series  of  its  own  metamorphoses,  and  completes  the  metamor- 
phosis of  another  (the  wheat).  In  the  first  phase  or  sale,  the  linen 
plays  these  two  parts  in  its  own  person.  But,  then,  changed 
into  gold,  it  completes  its  own  second  and  final  metamorphosis, 
and  helps  at  the  same  time  to  accomplish  the  first  metamor- 
phosis of  a  third  commodity.  Hence  the  circuit  made  by  one 
commodity  in  the  course  of  its  metamorphoses  is  inextricably 
mixed  up  with  the  circuits  of  other  commodities.     The  total 

^  "II  y  a  done  .  .  .  quatre  termes  et  trois  contractants,  dont  I'un  intervient  deux 
fois."    (Le  Trosne  1.  c.  p.  909.) 


86  Capitalist  Prodtcction. 

of  all  the  different  circuits  constitutes  the  circulation  of  com- 
modities. 

The  circulation  of  commodities  differs  from  the  direct  ex- 
change of  products  (barter),  not  onl}''  in  form,  but  in  substance. 
Only  consider  the  course  of  events.  The  weaver  has,  as  a 
matter  of  fact,  exchanged  his  linen  for  a  Bible,  his  own  com- 
modity for  that  of  some  one  else.  But  this  is  true  only  so  far 
as  he  himself  is  concerned.  The  seller  of  the  Bible,  who  prefers 
something  to  warm  his  inside,  no  more  thought  of  exchanging 
his  Bible  for  linen  than  our  weaver  knew  that  wheat  had  been 
exchanged  for  his  linen.  B's  commodity  replaces  that  of  A, 
but  A  and  B  do  not  mutually  exchange  those  commodities. 
It  may,  of  course,  happen  that  A  and  B  make  simultaneous 
purchases,  the  one  from  the  other ;  but  such  exceptional  trans- 
actions are  by  no  means  the  necessary  result  of  the  general  con- 
ditions of  the  circulation  of  commodities.  We  see  here,  on 
the  one  hand,  how  the  exchange  of  commodities  breaks  through 
all  local  and  personal  bounds  inseparable  from  direct  barter,  and 
develops  the  circulation  of  the  products  of  social  labour ;  and 
on  the  other  hand,  how  it  develops  a  whole  network  of  social 
relations  spontaneous  in  their  growth  and  entirely  beyond  the 
control  of  the  actors.  It  is  only  because  the  farmer  has  sold 
his  wheat  that  the  weaver  is  enabled  to  sell  his  linen,  only 
because  the  weaver  has  sold  his  linen  that  our  Hotspur  is 
enabled  to  sell  his  Bible,  and  only  because  the  latter  has  sold 
the  water  of  everlasting  life  that  the  distiller  is  enabled  to  sell 
his  eaU'de-vie,  and  so  on. 

The  process  of  circulation,  therefore,  does  not,  like  direct 
barter  of  products,  become  extinguished  upon  the  use  values 
changing  places  and  hands.  The  money  does  not  vanish  on 
dropping  out  of  the  circuit  of  the  metamorphosis  of  a  given 
commodity.  It  is  constantly  being  precipitated  into  new 
places  in  the  arena  of  circulation  vacated  by  other  commodities. 
In  the  complete  metamorphosis  of  the  linen,  for  example,  linen — 
money — Bible,  the  linen  first  falls  out  of  circulation,  and  money 
steps  into  its  place.  Then  the  Bible  falls  out  of  circulation,  and 
again  money  takes  its  place.  When  one  commodity  replaces 
another,  the  money  commodity  always  sticks  to  the  hands  of 


Money^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.      87 

some  third  person.  ^      Circulation  sweats  money   from  every 
pore. 

Nothing  can  be  more  childish  than  the  dogma,  that  because 
every  sale  is  a  purchase,  and  every  purchase  a  sale,  therefore 
the  circulation  of  commodities  necessarily  implies  an  equili- 
brium of  sales  and  purchases.  If  this  means  that  the  number 
of  actual  sales  is  equal  to  the  number  of  purchases,  it  is  mere 
tautology.  But  its  real  purport  is  to  prove  that  every  seller 
brings  his  buyer  to  market  with  him.  Nothing  of  the  kind. 
The  sale  and  the  purchase  constitute  one  identical  act,  an 
exchange  between  a  commodity -owner  and  an  owner  of  money, 
between  two  persons  as  opposed  to  each  other  as  the  two  poles 
of  a  magnet.  They  form  two  distinct  acts,  of  polar  and 
opposite  characters,  when  performed  by  one  single  person. 
Hence  the  identity  of  sale  and  purchase  implies  that  the 
commodity  is  useless,  if,  on  being  thrown  into  the  alchemistical 
retort  of  circulation,  it  does  not  come  out  again  in  the  shape 
of  money;  if,  in  other  words,  it  cannot  be  sold  by  its  owner,  and 
therefore  be  bought  by  the  owner  of  the  money.  That  identity 
further  implies  that  the  exchange,  if  it  do  take  place,  constitutes 
a  period  of  rest,  an  interval,  long  or  short,  in  the  life  of  the 
commodity.  Since  the  first  metamorphosis  of  a  commodity  is 
at  once  a  sale  and  a  purchase,  it  is  also  an  independent  process 
in  itself  The  purchaser  has  the  commodity,  the  seller  has  the 
money,  ^.e.,  a  commodity  ready  to  go  into  circulation  at  any 
time.  No  one  can  sell  unless  some  one  else  purchases.  But  no 
one  is  forthwith  bound  to  purchase,  because  he  has  just  sold. 
Circulation  bursts  through  all  restrictions  as  to  time,  place,  and 
individuals,  imposed  by  direct  barter,  and  this  it  effects  by 
splitting  up,  into  the  antithesis  of  a  sale  and  a  purchase,  the 
direct  identity  that  in  barter  does  exist  between  the  alienation 
of  one's  own  and  the  acquisition  of  some  other  man's  product. 
To  say  that  these  two  independent  and  antithetical  acts  have 
an  intrinsic  unity,  are  essentially  one,  is  the  same  as  to  say 
that  this  intrinsic  oneness  expresses  itself  in  an  external 
antithesis.     If  the  interval  in  time  between  the  two  comple- 

1    Self-evident  as  this  may  be,  it  is  nevertheless  for  the  most  part  unobserved  by 
political  economists,  and  especially  by  the  "Freetrader  Vulgaris." 


88  Capitalist  Production. 

mentary  phases  of  the  complete  metamorphosis  of  a  commodity 
become  too  great,  if  the  split  between  the  sale  and  the  purchase 
become  too  pronounced,  the  intimate  connexion  between  them, 
their  oneness,  asserts  itself  by  producing — a  crisis.  The 
antithesis, use- value  and  value;  the  contradictions  that  private 
labour  is  bound  to  manifest  itself  as  direct  social  labour,  that  a 
particularized  concrete  kind  of  labour  has  to  pass  for  abstract 
human  labour;  the  contradiction  between  the  personification 
of  objects  and  the  representation  of  persons  by  things ;  all  these 
antitheses  and  contradictions,  which  are  immanent  in  com- 
modities, assert  themselves,  and  develop  their  modes  of  motion, 
in  the  antithetical  phases  of  the  metamorphosis  of  a  commodity. 
These  modes  therefore  imply  the  possibility,  and  no  more  than 
the  possibility,  of  crises.  The  conversion  of  this  mere  possibility 
into  a  reality  is  the  result  of  a  long  series  of  relations,  that, 
from  our  present  standpoint  of  simple  circulation,  have  as  yet 
no  existence.  ^ 

h  The  cwn^ency'^  of  money. 

The  change  of  form,  C — M — C,  by  which  the  circulation  of 
the  material  products  of  labour  is  brought  about,  requires  that 
a  given  value  in  the  shape  of  a  commodity  shall  begin  the  pro- 
cess, and  shall,  also  in  the  shape  of  a  commodity,  end  it.  The 
movement  of  the  commodity  is  therefore  a  circuit.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  form  of  this  movement  precludes  a  circuit  from 

1  See  my  observations  on  James  Mill  in  ''Zur  Kritik,  &c.,"  p.  74-76.  With  regard 
to  this  subject,  we  may  notice  two  methods  characteristic  of  apologetic  economy.  The 
first  is  the  identification  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  with  the  direct  barter  of 
products,  by  simple  abstraction  from  their  points  of  difference ;  the  second  is,  the 
attempt  to  explain  away  the  contradictions  of  capitalist  production,  by  reducing  the 
relations  between  the  persons  engaged  in  that  mode  of  production,  to  the  simple  rela- 
tions arising  out  of  the  circulation  of  commodities.  The  production  and  circulation 
of  commodities  are,  however,  phenomena  that  occur  to  a  greater  or  less  extent  in 
modes  of  production  the  most  diverse.  If  we  are  acquainted  with  nothing  but  the 
abstract  categories  of  circulation,  which  are  common  to  all  these  modes  of  production, 
we  cannot  possibly  know  anything  of  the  specific  points  of  difference  of  those  modes, 
nor  pronounce  any  judgment  upon  them.  In  no  science  is  such  a  big  fuss  made  with 
commonplace  truisms  as  in  political  economy.  For  instance,  J.  B.  Say  sets  himself 
up  as  a  judge  of  crises,  because,  forsooth,  he  knows  that  a  commodity  is  a  product. 

2  Translator's  note. — This  word  is  here  used  in  its  original  signification  of  the 
course  or  track  pursued  by  money  as  it  changes  from  hand  to  hand,  a  course  which 
essentially  differs  from  circulation. 


Money,  or  the   Circulation  of  Commodities.      89 

being  made  by  the  money.  The  result  is  not  the  return  of  the 
money,  but  its  continued  removal  further  and  further  away 
from  its  starting-point.  So  long  as  the  seller  sticks  fast  to  his 
money,  which  is  the  transformed  shape  of  his  commodity,  that 
commodity  is  still  in  the  first  phase  of  its  metamorphosis,  and 
has  completed  only  half  its  course.  But  so  soon  as  he  com- 
pletes the  process,  so  soon  as  he  supplements  his  sale  by  a  pur- 
chase, the  money  again  leaves  the  hands  of  its  possessor.  It 
is  true  that  if  the  weaver,  after  buying  the  Bible,  sell  more  linen, 
money  comes  back  into  his  hands.  But  this  return  is  not 
owing  to  the  circulation  of  the  first  20  yards  of  linen ;  that  cir- 
culation resulted  in  the  money  getting  into  the  hands  of  the 
.seller  of  the  Bible.  The  return  of  money  into  the  hands  of  the 
weaver  is  brought  about  only  by  the  renewal  or  repetition  of 
the  process  of  circulation  with  a  fresh  commodity,  which 
renewed  process  ends  with  the  same  result  as  its  predecessor 
did.  Hence  the  movement  directly  imparted  to  money  by  the 
circulation  of  commodities  takes  the  form  of  a  constant  motion 
away  from  its  starting-point,  of  a  course  from  the  hands  of  one 
commodity  owner  into  those  of  another.  This  course  consti- 
tutes its  currency  (cours  de  la  monnaie). 

The  currency  of  money  is  the  constant  and  monotonous  re- 
petition of  the  same  process.  The  commodity  is  alwaj^s  in  the 
hands  of  the  seller ;  the  money,  as  a  means  of  purchase,  always 
in  the  hands  of  the  buyer.  And  money  serves  as  a  means  of 
purchase  by  realising  the  price  of  the  commodity.  This  reali- 
sation transfers  the  commodity  from  the  seller  to  the  buyer, 
and  removes  the  money  from  the  hands  of  the  buyer  into  those 
of  the  seller,  where  it  again  goes  through  the  same  process  with 
another  commodity.  That  this  one-sided  character  of  the 
money's  motion  arises  out  of  the  two-sided  character  of  the 
commodity's  motion,  is  a  circumstance  that  is  veiled  over.  The 
very  nature  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  begets  the  op- 
posite appearance.  The  first  metamorphosis  of  a  commodity  is 
visibly,  not  only  the  money's  movement,  but  also  that  of  the 
commodity  itself ;  in  the  second  metamorphosis,  on  the  con- 
trary, the  movement  appears  to  us  as  the  movement  of  the 
money  alone.     In  the  first  phase  of  its  circulation  the  com- 


90  Capitalist  Production. 

modity  changes  place  with  the  money.  Thereupon  the  com- 
modity, under  its  aspect  of  a  useful  object,  falls  out  of 
circulation  into  consumption.^  In  its  stead  we  have  its  value- 
shape — the  money.  It  then  goes  through  the  second  phase  of 
its  circulation,  not  under  its  own  natural  shape,  but  under  the 
shape  of  money.  The  continuity  of  the  movement  is  therefore 
kept  up  by  the  money  alone,  and  the  same  movement  that  as 
regards  the  commodity  consists  of  two  processes  of  an  anti- 
thetical character,  is,  when  considered  as  the  movement  of 
the  money,  always  one  and  the  same  process,  a  continued 
change  of  places  with  ever  fresh  commodities.  Hence  the 
result  brought  about  by  the  circulation  of  commodities,  namely, 
the  replacing  of  one  commodity  by  another,  takes  the  appear- 
ance of  having  been  effected  not  by  means  of  the  change  of 
form  of  the  commodities,  but  rather  hy  the  money  acting  as  a 
medium  of  circulation,  by  an  action  that  circulates  commodi- 
ties, to  all  appearance  motionless  in  themselves,  and  transfers 
them  from  hands  in  which  they  are  non-use-values,  to  hands  in 
which  they  are  use-values ;  and  that  in  a  direction  constantly 
opposed  to  the  direction  of  the  money.  The  latter  is  con- 
tinually withdrawing  commodities  from  circulation  and  step- 
ping into  their  places,  and  in  this  way  continually  moving 
further  and  further  from  its  starting-point.  Hence,  although 
the  movement  of  the  money  is  merely  the  expression  of 
the  circulation  of  commodities,  yet  the  contrary  appears  to  be 
the  actual  fact,  and  the  circulation  of  commodities  seems  to  be 
the  result  of  the  movement  of  the  money.^ 

Again,  money  functions  as  a  means  of  circulation,  only 
because  in  it  the  values  of  commodities  have  independent 
realit}^  Hence  its  movement,  as  the  medium  of  circulation,  is, 
in  fact,  merely  the  movement  of  commodities  while  changing 
their  forms.  This  fact  must  therefore  make  itself  plainly  visible 
in  the  currency  of  money.     The  twofold  change  of  form  in  a 

1  Even  when  the  commodity  is  sold  over  and  over  again,  a  phenomenon  that  at 
I>resent  has  no  existence  for  us,  it  falls,  when  definitely  sold  for  the  last  time,  out  of 
the  sphere  of  circulation  into  that  of  consumption,  where  it  serves  either  as  means  of 
subsistence  or  means  of  production. 

2  "  II  (I'argent)  n'a  d'autre  mouvement  que  celui  qui  lui  est  imprimS  par  les  pro- 
ductions."   (Le  Trosne  I.e. p.  885.) 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.        9 1 

commodity  is  reflected  in  the  twice  repeated  change  of  place  of 
the  same  piece  of  money  during  the  complete  metamorphosis  of 
a  commodity,  and  in  its  constantly  repeated  change  of  place, 
as  metamorphosis  follows  metamorphosis,  and  each  becomes 
interlaced  with  the  others. 

The  linen,  for  instance,  first  of  all  exchanges  its  commodity- 
form  for  its  money-form.  The  last  term  of  its  first  metamor- 
phosis (C — M),  or  the  money-form,  is  the  first  term  of  its  final 
metamorphosis  (M — C),  of  its  re-conversion  into  a  useful  commo- 
dity, the  Bible.  But  each  of  these  changes  of  form  is  accom- 
plished by  an  exchange  between  commodity  and  money,  by 
their  reciprocal  displacement.  The  same  pieces  of  coin,  in  the 
first  act,  changed  places  with  the  linen,  in  the  second,  with  the 
Bible.  They  are  displaced  twice.  The  first  metamorphosis 
puts  them  into  the  weaver's  pocket,  the  second  draws  them  out 
of  it.  The  two  inverse  changes  undergone  by  the  same  com- 
modity are  reflected  in  the  displacement,  twice  repeated,  but 
in  opposite  directions,  of  the  same  pieces  of  coin. 

If,  on  the  contrary,  only  one  phase  of  the  metamorphosis  is 
gone  through,  if  there  are  only  sales  or  only  purchases,  then  a 
given  piece  of  money  changes  its  place  only  once.  Its  second 
change  corresponds  to  and  expresses  the  second  metamorphosis 
of  the  commodity,  its  re-conversion  from  money  into  another 
commodity  intended  for  use.  It  is  a  matter  of  course,  that  all 
this  is  applicable  to  the  simple  circulation  of  commodities 
alone,  the  only  form  that  we  are  now  considering. 

Every  commodity,  when  it  first  steps  into  circulation,  and 
undergoes  its  first  change  of  form,  does  so  only  to  fall  out  of 
circulation  again  and  to  be  replaced  by  other  commodities. 
Money,  on  the  contrary,  as  the  medium  of  circulation,  keeps 
continually  within  the  sphere  of  circulation,  and  moves  about 
in  it.  The  question  therefore  arises,  how  much  money  this 
sphere  constantly  absorbs  ? 

In  a  given  country  there  take  place  every  day  at  the  same 
time,  but  in  diflferent  localities,  numerous  one-sided  metamor- 
phoses of  commodities,  or,  in  other  words,  numerous  sales  and 
numerous  purchases.  The  commodities  are  equated  before- 
hand in  imagination,  by  their  prices,  to  definite  quantities  of 


92  Capitalist  Production. 

money.  And  since,  in  the  form  of  circulation  now  under  con- 
sideration, money  and  commodities  always  come  bodily  face  to 
face,  one  at  the  positive  pole  of  purchase,  the  other  at  the 
negative  pole  of  sale,  it  is  clear  that  the  amount  of  the  means 
of  circulation  required,  is  determined  beforehand  by  the  sum  of 
the  prices  of  all  these  commodities.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  the 
money  in  reality  represents  the  quantity  or  sum  of  gold  ideally 
expressed  beforehand  by  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  the  com- 
modities. The  equality  of  these  two  sums  is  therefore  self- 
evident.  We  know,  however,  that,  the  values  of  commodities 
remaining  constant,  their  prices  vary  with  the  value  of  gold 
(the  material  of  money),  rising  in  proportion  as  it  falls,  and 
falling  in  proportion  as  it  rises.  Now  if,  in  consequence  of 
such  a  rise  or  fall  in  the  value  of  gold,  the  sum  of  the  prices  of 
commodities  fall  or  rise,  the  quantity  of  money  in  currency 
must  fall  or  rise  to  the  same  extent.  The  change  in  the 
quantity  of  the  circulating  medium  is,  in  this  case,  it  is  true, 
caused  by  the  money  itself,  yet  not  in  virtue  of  its  function 
as  a  medium  of  circulation,  but  of  its  function  as  a  measure  of 
value.  First,  the  price  of  the  commodities  varies  inversely 
as  the  value  of  the  money,  and  then  the  quantity  of  the 
medium  of  circulation  varies  directly  as  the  price  of  the 
commodities.  Exactly  the  same  thing  would  happen  if,  for 
instance,  instead  of  the  value  of  gold  falling,  gold  were  replaced 
by  silver  as  the  measure  of  value,  or  if,  instead  of  the  value  of 
silver  rising,  gold  were  to  thrust  silver  out  from  being  the 
measure  of  value.  In  the  one  case,  more  silver  would  be 
current  than  gold  was  before ;  in  the  other  case,  less  gold 
would  be  current  than  silver  was  before.  In  each  case  the 
value  of  the  material  of  money,  i.e.,  the  value  of  the  com- 
modity that  serves  as  the  measure  of  value,  would  have  under- 
gone a  change,  and  therefore  so,  too,  would  the  prices  of  com- 
modities which  express  their  values  in  money,  and  so,  too, 
would  the  quantity  of  money  current  whose  function  it  is  to 
realise  those  prices.  We  have  already  seen,  that  the  sphere  of 
circulation  has  an  opening  through  which  gold  (or  the  material 
of  money  generally)  enters  into  it  as  a  commodity  with  a  given 
value.      Hence,   when   money   enters   on   its   functions   as   a 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.        93 

measure  of  value,  when  it  expresses  prices,  its  value  is  already 
determined.  If  now  its  value  fall,  this  fact  is  first  evidenced 
by  a  change  in  the  prices  of  those  commodities  that  are 
directly  bartered  for  the  precious  metals  at  the  sources  of 
their  production.  The  greater  part  of  all  other  commodities, 
especially  in  the  imperfectly  developed  stages  of  civil  society, 
will  continue  for  a  long  time  to  be  estimated  by  the  former 
antiquated  and  illusory  value  of  the  measure  of  value. 
Nevertheless,  one  commodity  infects  another  through  their 
common  value-relation,  so  that  their  prices,  expressed  in  gold 
or  in  silver,  gradually  settle  down  into  the  proportions  detei- 
mined  by  their  comparative  values,  until  finally  the  values  of 
all  commodities  are  estimated  in  terms  of  the  new  value  of  the 
metal  that  constitutes  money.  This  process  is  accompanied  by 
the  continued  increase  in  the  quantity  of  the  precious  metals, 
an  increase  caused  by  their  streaming  in  to  replace  the  articles 
directly  bartered  for  them  at  their  sources  of  production.  In 
proportion  therefore  as  commodities  in  general  acquire  their 
true  prices,  in  proportion  as  their  values  become  estimated 
according  to  the  fallen  value  of  the  precious  metal,  in  the 
same  proportion  the  quantity  of  that  metal  necessary  for  realis- 
ing those  new  prices  is  provided  beforehand.  A  one-sided 
observation  of  the  results  that  followed  upon  the  discovery  of 
fresh  supplies  of  gold  and  silver,  led  some  economists  in  the 
17th,  and  particularly  in  the  18th  century,  to  the  false  con- 
clusion, that  the  prices  of  commodities  had  gone  up  in  conse- 
quence of  the  increased  quantity  of  gold  and  silver  serving  g,s 
means  of  circulation.  Henceforth  we  shall  consider  the  value 
of  gold  to  be  given,  as,  in  fact,  it  is  momentarily  whenever  we 
estimate  the  price  of  a  commodity. 

On  this  supposition  then,  the  quantity  of  the  medium  of 
circulation  is  determined  by  the  sum  of  the  prices  that  have  to 
be  realised.  If  now  we  further  suppose  the  price  of  each  com- 
modity to  be  given,  the  sum  of  the  prices  clearly  depends  on 
the  mass  of  commodities  in  circulation.  It  requires  but  little 
racking  of  brains  to  comprehend  that  if  one  quarter  of  wheat 
costs  £2,  100  quarters  will  cost  £200,  200  quarters  £400,  and 
so  on,  that  consequently  the  quantity  of  money  that  changes 


94  Capitalist  Production. 

place  with  the  wheat,  when  sold,  must  increase  with  the  quan- 
tity of  that  wheat. 

If  the  mass  of  commodities  remain  constant,  the  quantity  of 
circulating  money  varies  with  the  fluctuations  in  the  prices  of 
those  commodities.  It  increases  and  diminishes  because  the 
sum  of  the  prices  increases  or  diminishes  in  consequence  of  the 
change  of  price.  To  produce  this  effect,  it  is  by  no  means 
requisite  that  the  prices  of  all  commodities  should  rise  or  fall 
simultaneously.  A  rise  or  a  fall  in  the  prices  of  a  number  of 
leading  articles,  is  sufficient  in  the  one  case  to  increase,  in  the 
other  to  diminish,  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  all  commodities, 
and,  therefore,  to  put  more  or  less  money  in  circulation. 
Whether  the  change  in  the  price  correspond  to  an  actual 
change  of  value  in  the  commodities,  or  whether  it  be  the  result 
of  mere  fluctuations  in  market  prices,  the  effect  on  the  quan- 
tity of  the  medium  of  circulation  remains  the  same. 

Suppose  the  following  articles  to  be  sold  or  partially  meta- 
morphosed simultaneously  in  difierent  localities  :  say,  one 
<|uarter  of  wheat,  20  yards  of  linen,  one  Bible,  and  4  gallons  of 
brandy.  If  the  price  of  each  article  be  £2,  and  the  sum  of  the 
prices  to  be  realised  be  consequently  £8,  it  follows  that  £8  in 
money  must  go  into  circulation.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  these 
same  articles  are  links  in  the  following  chain  of  metamorphoses : 
1  quarter  of  wheat — £2 — 20  yards  of  linen — £2 — 1  Bible — 
£2 — 4  gallons  of  brandy — £2,  a  chain  that  is  already  well- 
known  to  us,  in  that  case  the  £2  cause  the  difierent  com- 
modities to  circulate  one  after  the  other,  and  after  realizing 
their  prices  successively,  and  therefore  the  sum  of  those  prices, 
£8,  they  come  to  rest  at  last  in  the  pocket  of  the  distiller.  The 
£2  thus  make  four  moves.  This  repeated  change  of  place  of  the 
same  pieces  of  money  corresponds  to  the  double  change  in  form 
of  the  commodities,  to  their  motion  in  opposite  directions 
through  two  stages  of  circulation,  and  to  the  interlacing  of  the 
metamorphoses  of  diflferent  commodities.^  These  antithetic  and 
complementary  phases,  of  which  the  process  of  metamorphosis 

^  "Ce  sont  les  productions  qui  le  (I'argent)  mettent  en  mouvement  et  le  font 
circular  ...  La  celerite  de  son  mouvement  (sc.  de  I'argent)  supplee  d,  sa  quantite 
Lorsqu'il  en  est  besoin,  il  ne  fait  que  glisser  d'une  main  dans  I'autre  sans  s'arreter  un 
instant."    (Le  Trosne  1.  c.  pp.  915,  916.) 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Com7nodities.        95 

consists,  are  gone  through,  not  simultaneously,  but  successively. 
Time  is  therefore  required  for  the  completion  of  the  series. 
Hence  the  velocity  of  the  currency  of  money  is  measured  by 
the  number  of  moves  made  by  a  given  piece  of  money  in  a 
given  time.  Suppose  the  circulation  of  the  4  articles  takes  a 
day.  The  sum  of  the  prices  to  be  realised  in  the  day  is  £8, 
the  number  of  moves  of  the  two  pieces  of  money  is  four,  and 
the  quantity  of  money  circulating  is  £2.  Hence,  for  a  given 
interval  of  time  during  the  process  of  circulation,  we  have  the 
following  relation :  the  quantity  of  money  functioning  as  the 
circulating  medium  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  the 
commodities  divided  by  the  number  of  moves  made  by  coins 
of  the  same  denomination.     This  law  holds  generally. 

The  total  circulation  of  commodities  in  a  given  country 
during  a  given  period  is  made  up  on  the  one  hand  of  numerous 
isolated  and  simultaneous  partial  metamorphoses,  sales  which 
are  at  the  same  time  purchases,  in  which  each  coin  changes  its 
place  only  once,  or  makes  only  one  move  ;  on  the  other  hand, 
of  numerous  distinct  series  of  metamorphoses  partly  running 
side  by  side,  and  partly  coalescing  with  each  other,  in  each  of 
which  series  each  coin  makes  a  number  of  moves,  the  number 
being  greater  or  less  according  to  circumstances.  The  total 
number  of  moves  made  by  all  the  circulating  coins  of  one 
denomination  being  given,  we  can  arrive  at  the  average  num- 
ber of  moves  made  by  a  single  coin  of  that  denomination,  or  at 
the  average  velocity  of  the  currency  of  money.  The  quantity 
of  money  thrown  into  the  circulation  at  the  beginning  of  each 
day  is  of  course  determined  by  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  all  the 
commodities  circulating  simultaneously  side  by  side.  But  once 
in  circulation,  coins  are,  so  to  say,  made  responsible  for  one 
another.  If  the  one  increase  its  velocity,  the  other  either 
retards  its  own,  or  altogether  falls  out  of  circulation ;  for  the 
circulation  can  absorb  only  such  a  quantity  of  gold  as  when 
multiplied  by  the  mean  number  of  moves  made  by  one  single 
coin  or  element,  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  the  prices  to  be  rea- 
lised. Hence  if  the  number  of  moves  made  by  the  separate 
pieces  increase,  the  total  number  of  those  pieces  in  circulation 
diminishes.     If  the  number  of  the  moves  diminish,  the  total 


96  Capitalist  Pj'odztction. 

number  of  pieces  increases.  Since  the  quantity  of  money  cap- 
able of  being  absorbed  by  the  circulation  is  given  for  a  given 
mean  velocity  of  currency,  all  that  is  necessary  in  order  to 
abstract  a  given  number  of  sovereigns  from  the  circulation  is  to 
throw  the  same  number  of  one-pound  notes  into  it,  a  trick  well 
known  to  all  bankers. 

Just  as  the  currency  of  money,  generally  considered,  is  but 
a  reflex  of  the  circulation  of  commodities,  or  of  the  antithetical 
metamorphoses  they  undergo,  so,  too,  the  velocity  of  that  cur- 
rency reflects  the  rapidity  with  which  commodities  change 
their  forms,  the  continued  interlacing  of  one  series  of  meta- 
morphoses with  another,  the  hurried  social  interchange  of 
matter,  the  rapid  disappearance  of  commodities  from  the 
sphere  of  circulation,  and  the  equally  rapid  substitution  of 
fresh  ones  in  their  places.  Hence,  in  the  velocity  of  the  cur- 
rency we  have  the  fluent  unity  of  the  antithetical  and  com- 
plementary phases,  the  unity  of  the  conversion  of  the  useful 
aspect  of  commodities  into  their  value-aspect,  and  their  re-con- 
version from  the  latter  aspect  to  the  former,  or  the  unity  of  the 
two  processes  of  sale  and  purchase.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
retardation  of  the  currency  reflects  the  separation  of  these  two 
processes  into  isolated  antithetical  phases,  reflects  the  stagna- 
tion in  the  change  of  form,  and  therefore,  in  the  social  inter- 
change of  matter.  The  circulation  itself,  of  course,  gives  no 
clue  to  the  origin  of  this  stagnation ;  it  merely  puts  in  evidence 
the  phenomenon  itself.  The  general  public,  who,  simultane- 
ously, with  the  retardation  of  the  currency,  see  money  appear 
and  disappear  less  frequently  at  the  periphery  of  cii^culation, 
naturally  attribute  this  retardation  to  a  quantitative  deficiency 
in  the  circulating  medium.^ 

1  Money  being.  .  .  the  common  measure  of  buying  and  selling,  every  body  who 
hath  anything  to  sell,  and  cannot  procure  chapmen  for  it,  is  presently  apt  to  think, 
that  want  of  money  in  the  kingdom,  or  country,  is  the  cause  why  his  goods  do  not 
go  off ;  and  so,  want  of  money  is  the  common  cry ;  which  is  a  great  mistake.  .  . 
What  do  these  peoi)le  want,  who  cry  out  for  money  ?  .  .  .  The  farmer  complains 
...  he  thinks  that  were  more  money  in  the  country,  he  should  have  a  price  for  his 
goods.  Then  it  seems  money  is  not  his  want,  but  a  price  for  his  corn  and  cattel,  which 
he  would  sell,  but  cannot.  .  .  Why  cannot  he  get  a  price  ?...(!)  Either  there  is 
too  much  corn  and  cattel  in  the  country,  so  that  most  who  come  to  market  have 
need  of  selling,  as  he  hath,  and  few  of  buying ;  or  (2)  There  wants  the  usual  vent 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.        97 

The  totaJ  quantity  of  money  functioning  during  a  given 
period  as  the  circulating  medium,  is  determined,  on  the  one 
hand,  by  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  the  circulating  commodities, 
and  on  the  other  hand,  by  the  rapidity  with  which  the  anti- 
thetical phases  of  the  metamorphoses  follow  one  another.  On 
this  rapidity  depends  what  proportion  of  the  sum  of  the  prices 
can,  on  the  average,  be  realised  by  each  single  coin.  But  the 
sum  of  the  prices  of  the  circulating  commodities  depends  on 
the  quantity,  as  well  as  on  the  prices,  of  the  commodities. 
These  three  factors,  however,  state  of  prices,  quantity  of  circu- 
lating commodities,  and  velocity  of  money-currency,  are  all 
variable.  Hence,  the  sum  of  the  prices  to  be  realised,  and 
consequently  the  quantity  of  the  circulating  medium  depend- 
ing on  that  sum,  will  vary  with  the  numerous  variations  of 
these  three  factors  in  combination.  Of  these  variations  we 
shall  consider  those  alone  that  have  been  the  most  important 
in  the  history  of  prices. 

While  prices  remain  constant,  the  quantity  of  the  circulat- 
ing medium  may  increase  owing  to  the  number  of  circulating 
commodities  increasing,  or  to  the  velocity  of  currency  decreas- 
ing, or  to  a  combination  of  the  two.  On  the  other  hand  the 
quantity  of  the  circulating  medium  may  decrease  with  a 
decreasing  number  of  commodities,  or  with  an  increasing 
rapidity  of  their  circulation. 

With  a  general  rise  in  the  prices  of  commodities,  the  quantity 
of  the  circulating  medium  will  remain  constant,  provided  the 
number  of  commodities  in  circulation  decrease  proportionally 

abroad  by  transportation.  .  .  ;  or  (3)  The  consumption  fails,  as  when  men,  by  reason 
of  poverty,  do  not  spend  so  much  in  their  houses  as  formerly  they  did ;  wherefore  it 
is  not  the  increase  of  specific  money,  which  would  at  all  advance  the  farmer's  goods, 
but  the  removal  of  any  of  these  three  causes,  which  do  truly  keep  down  the  market. 
.  .  .  The  merchant  and  shoiDkeeper  want  money  in  the  same  manner,  that  is,  they 
want  a  vent  for  the  goods  they  deal  in,  by  reason  that  the  markets  fail "...  [A 
nation]  "never  thrives  better,  than  when  riches  are  tost  from  hand  to  hand."  (Sir 
Dudley  North  :  **  Discourses  upon  Trade,"  Lond.  1691,  pp.  11-15,  passim.)  Herren- 
schwand's  fanciful  notions  amount  merely  to  this,  that  the  antagonism,  which  has- 
its  origin  in  the  nature  of  commodities,  and  is  reproduced  in  their  circulation,  can  be 
removed  by  increasing  the  circulating  medium.  But  if,  on  the  one  hand,  it  is  a  popu- 
lar delusion  to  ascribe  stagnation  in  production  and  circulation  to  insuflSciency  of 
the  circulating  medium,  it  by  no  means  follows,  on  the  other  hand,  that  an  actual 
paucity  of  the  medium  in  consequence,  e.g.^  of  bungling  legislative  interference  with. 
the  regulation  of  currency,  may  not  give  rise  to  such  stagnation. 

G 


98  Capitalist  Prcduction. 

to  the  increase  in  their  prices,  or  provided  the  velocity  of 
currency  increase  at  the  same  rate  as  prices  rise,  the  number  of 
commodities  in  circulation  remaining  constant.  The  quantity 
of  the  circulating  medium  may  decrease,  owing  to  the  number 
of  commodities  decreasing  more  rapidly ;  or  to  the  velocity  of 
currency  increasing  more  rapidly,  than  prices  rise. 

With  a  general  fall  in  the  prices  of  commodities,  the  quantity 
of  the  circulating  medium  will  remain  constant,  provided  the 
number  of  commodities  increase  proportionally  to  their  fall  in 
price,  or  provided  the  velocity  of  currency  decrease  in  the  same 
proportion.  The  quantity  of  the  circulating  medium  will 
increase,  provided  the  number  of  commodities  increase  quicker, 
or  the  rapidity  of  circulation  decrease  quicker,  than  the  prices 
fall. 

The  variations  of  the  different  factors  may  mutually  compen- 
sate each  other,  so  that  notwithstanding  their  continued 
instability,  the  sum  of  the  prices  to  be  realised  and  the  quantity 
of  money  in  circulation  remains  constant;  consequently,  we 
find,  especially  if  we  take  long  periods  into  consideration,  that 
the  deviations  from  the  average  level,  of  the  quantity  of  money 
current  in  any  country,  are  much  smaller  than  we  should  at 
first  sight  expect,  apart  of  course  from  excessive  perturbations 
periodically  arising  from  industrial  and  commercial  crises,  or, 
less  frequently,  from  fluctuations  in  the  value  of  money. 

The  law,  that  the  quantity  of  the  circulating  medium  is 
determined  by  the  sum  of  the  prices  of  the  commodities 
circulating,  and  the  average  velocity  of  currency  ^  may  also  be 

1  "There  is  a  certain  measure  and  proportion  of  money  requisite  to  drive  the 
trade  of  a  nation,  more  or  less  than  which  would  prejudice  the  same.  Just  as  there 
is  a  certain  proportion  of  farthings  necessary  in  a  small  retail  trade,  to  change  silver 
money,  and  to  even  such  reckonings  as  cannot  be  adjusted  with  the  smallest  silver 
pieces.  .  .  .  Now,  as  the  proportion  of  the  number  of  farthings  requisite  in  com- 
merce is  to  be  taken  from  the  number  of  people,  the  frequency  of  their  exchanges : 
as  also,  and  principally,  from  the  value  of  the  smallest  silver  pieces  of  money ;  so  in 
like  manner,  the  proportion  of  money  [gold  and  silver  specie]  requisite  in  our  trade, 
is  to  be  likewise  taken  from  the  frequency  of  commutations,  and  from  the  bigness  of 
the  payments."  (William  Petty.  "  A  Treatise  on  Taxes  and  Contributions."  Lond. 
1662,  p.  17.)  The  Theory  of  Hume  was  defended  against  the  attacks  of  J.  Steuart  and 
others,  by  A.  Young,  in  his  "Political  Arithmetic,"  Lond.  1774,  in  which  work  there 
is  a  special  chapter  entitled  "Prices  depend  on  quantity  of  money,"  at  p.  112,  sqq. 
J  have  stated  in   "Zur  Kritik,   &c.,"  p.    149:    "He   (Adam   Smith)   passes  over 


Money^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,        99 

stated  as  follows :  given  the  sum  of  the  values  of  commodities, 
and  the  average  rapidity  of  their  metamorphoses,  the  quantity 
of  precious  metal  current  as  money  depends  on  the  value  of 
that  precious  metal.  The  erroneous  opinion  that  it  is,  on  the 
contrary,  prices  that  are  determined  by  the  quantity  of  the 
circulating  medium,  and  that  the  latter  depends  on  the 
quantity  of  the  precious  metals  in  a  country ;  ^  this  opinion  was 
based  by  those  who  first  held  it,  on  the  absurd  hypothesis  that 
commodities  are  without  a  price,  and  money  without  a  value, 
when  they  first  enter  into  circulation,  and  that,  once  in  the 
circulation,  an  aliquot  part  of  the  medley  of  commodities  is 
exchanged  for  an  aliquot  part  of  the  heap  of  precious  metals.  ^ 

without  remark  the  question  as  to  the  quantity  of  coin  in  circulation,  and  treats 
money  quite  wrongly  as  a  mere  commodity."  This  statement  applies  only  in  so  far 
as  Adam  Smith,  ex  officio,  treats  of  money.  Now  and  then,  however,  as  in  his 
criticism  of  the  earlier  systems  of  political  economy,  he  takes  the  right  view.  "  The 
quantity  of  coin  in  every  country  is  regulated  by  the  value  of  the  commodities  which 
are  to  be  circulated  by  it.  .  .  .  The  value  of  the  goods  annually  bought  and  sold 
in  any  country  requires  a  certain  quantity  of  money  to  circulate  and  distribute  them 
to  their  proper  consumers,  and  can  give  employment  to  no  more.  The  channel  of 
circulation  necessarily  draws  to  itself  a  sum  sufficient  to  fill  it,  and  never  admits  any 
more."  ("  Wealth  of  Nations."  Bk.  IV.,  ch.  I.)  In  like  manner,  ex  officio,  he  opens 
his  work  with  an  apotheosis  on  the  division  of  labour.  Afterwards,  in  the  last  book 
which  treats  of  the  sources  of  public  revenue,  he  occasionally  repeats  the  denunciations 
of  the  division  of  labour  made  by  his  teacher,  A.  Ferguson. 

1  "The  prices  of  things  will  certainly  rise  in  every  nation,  as  the  gold  and  silver 
increase  amongst  the  people ;  and  consequently,  where  the  gold  and  silver  decrease 
in  any  nation,  the  prices  of  all  things  must  fall  proportionably  to  such  decrease  of 
money."  (Jacob  Vanderlint :  "Money  answers  all  Things."  Lond.  1734,  p.  5.)  A 
careful  coniparison  of  this  book  with  Hume's  "Essays,"  proves  to  my  mind  without 
doubt  that  Hume  was  acquainted  with  and  made  use  of  Vanderlint's  work,  which  is 
certainly  an  important  one.  The  opinion  that  prices  are  determined  by  the  quantity 
of  the  circulating  medium,  was  also  held  by  Barbon  and  other  much  earlier  writers. 
"No  inconvenience,"  says  Vanderlint,  "can  arise  by  an  unrestrained  trade,  but  very 
great  advantage ;  since,  if  the  cash  of  the  nation  be  decreased  by  it,  which 
prohibitions  are  designed  to  prevent,  those  nations  that  get  the  cash  will  certainly 
find  everything  advance  in  price,  as  the  cash  increases  amongst  them.  And  .  .  . 
our  manufactures,  and  everything  else,  will  soon  become  so  moderate  as  to  turn  the 
balance  of  trade  in  our  favour,  and  thereby  fetch  the  money  back  again."  (1.  c, 
pp.  43,  44.) 

2  That  the  price  of  each  single  kind  of  commodity  forms  a  part  of  the  sum  of  the 
prices  of  all  the  commodities  in  circulation,  is  a  self-evident  proposition.  But  how 
use-values,  which  are  incommensurable  with  regard  to  each  other,  are  to  be  ex- 
changed, en  masse,  for  the  total  sum  of  gold  and  silver  in  a  country,  is  quite  incom- 
prehensible. If  we  start  from  the  notion  that  all  commodities  together  form  one 
single  commodity,  of  which  each  is  but  an  aliquot  part,  we  get  the  following  beautiful 
result :  The  total  commodity  =  x  c wt.  of  gold ;  commodity  A  =  an  aliquot  part  of  the 


lOO  Capitalist  Prodttdion, 

c.  Coin  and  symbols  of  value. 

That  money  takes  the  shape  of  coin,  springs  from  its  function 
as  the  circulating  medium.  The  weight  of  gold  represented  in 
imagination  by  the  prices  or  money-names  of  commodities, 
must  confront  those  commodities,  within  the  circulation,  in  the 
shape  of  coins  or  pieces  of  gold  of  a  given  denomination. 
Coining,  like  the  establishment  of  a  standard  of  prices,  is  the 
business  of  the  State.  The  different  national  uniforms  worn 
at  home  by  gold  and  silver  as  coins,  and  doffed  again  in  the 
market  of  the  world,  indicate  the  separation  between  the 
internal  or  national  spheres  of  the  circulation  of  commodities, 
and  their  universal  sphere. 

The  only  difference,  therefore,  between  coin  and  bullion,  is 
one  of  shape,  and  gold  can  at  any  time  pass  from  one  form  to 
the  other.^      But  no  sooner  does  coin  leave  the  mint,  than  it 

total  commodity  =  the  same  aliquot  part  of  x  cwt.  of  gold.  This  is  stated  in  all 
seriousness  by  Montesquieu  :  "Si  I'on  compare  la  masse  de  I'or  et  de  I'argent  qui  est 
dans  le  monde  avec  la  somme  des  marchandises  qui  y  sont,  il  est  certain  que  chaque 
denree  ou  marchandise,  en  j)articulier,  pourra  6tre  compar^e  fi  une  certaine  portion 
de  le  masse  entiere.  Supposons  qu'il  n'y  ait  qu'une  seule  denree  ou  marchandise  dans  le 
monde,  ou  qu'il  n'y  ait  qu'une  seule  qui  s'achete,  et  qu'elle  se  divise  comme  I'argent : 
Cette  partie  de  cette  marchandise  repondra  sL  une  partie  de  la  masse  de  I'argent ;  la 
moiti6  du  total  de  I'une  h,  la  moiti6  du  total  de  I'autre,  &c.  .  .  .  I'etablissemeut 
du  prix  des  choses  depend  toujours  fondamentalement  de  la  raison  du  total  des  choses 
au  total  des  signes."  (Montesquieu  1.  c.  t  III.,  pp.  12,  13.)  As  to  the  further  devel- 
opment of  this  theory  by  Ricardo  and  his  disciples,  James  Mill,  Lord  Overstone,  and 
others,  see  "Zur  KrJtik,"  &c.,  pp.  140-146,  and  p.  150,  sqq.  John  Stuart  Mill,  with 
his  usual  eclectic  logic,  understands  how  to  hold  at  the  same  time  the  view  of  his 
father,  James  Mill,  and  the  opposite  view.  On  a  comparison  of  the  text  of  his 
compendium,  ''Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.,"  with  his  preface  to  the  first  adition,  in 
which  preface  he  announces  himself  as  the  Adam  Smith  of  his  day — we  do  not  know 
whether  to  admire  more  the  simplicity  of  the  man,  or  that  of  the  public,  who  took 
him,  in  good  faith,  for  the  Adam  Smith  he  announced  himself  to  be,  although  he  bears 
about  as  much  resemblance  to  Adam  Smith  as  say  General  Williams,  of  Kars,  to  the 
Duke  of  Wellington.  The  original  researches  of  Mr.  J.  S.  Mill,  which  are  neither 
extensive  nor  profound,  in  the  domain  of  political  economy,  will  be  found  mustered 
in  rank  and  file  in  his  little  work,  "  Some  Unsettled  Questions  of  Political  Economy," 
which  appeared  in  1844.  Locke  asserts  point  blank  the  connexion  between  the 
absence  of  value  in  gold  and  silver,  and  the  determination  of  their  values  by  quantity 
alone,  "  Mankind  having  consented  to  put  an  imaginary  value  upon  gold  and  silver 
.  .  .  the  intrinsick  value,  regarded  in  these  metals,  is  nothing  but  the  quantity." 
("Some  considerations, "&c.,  1691,  AVorks  Ed.  1777,  vol.  IL,  p.  15.) 

1  It  lies,  of  course,  entirely  beyond  my  purpose  to  take  into  consideration  such 
details  as  the  seigniorage  on  minting.  I  will,  however,  cite  for  the  benefit  of  the 
romantic  sycophant,  Adam   BluUer,   who  admires  the  "generous  liberality"  with 


Money,  or  the  Ciradation  of  Commodities.     loi 

immediately  finds  itself  on  the  high-road  to  the  melting  pot. 
During  their  currency,  coins  wear  away,  some  more,  others 
less.  Name  and  substance,  nominal  weight  and  real  weight, 
begin  their  process  of  separation.  Coins  of  the  same  denom- 
ination become  different  in  value,  because  they  are  different  in 
weight.  The  weight  of  gold  fixed  upon  as  the  standard  of 
j^rices,  deviates  from  the  weight  that  serves  as  the  circulating 
medium,  and  the  latter  thereby  ceases  any  longer  to  be  a  real 
equivalent  of  the  commodities  whose  prices  it  realises.  The 
history  of  coinage  during  the  middle  ages  and  down  into  the 
18th  century,  records  the  ever  renewed  confusion  arising  from 
this  cause.  The  natural  tendency  of  circulation  to  convert 
coins  into  a  mere  semblance  of  what  they  profess  to  be,  into  a 
symbol  of  the  weight  of  metal  they  are  officially  supposed  to 
contain,  is  recognised  by  modern  legislation,  which  fixes  the 
loss  of  weight  sufficient  to  demonetise  a  gold  coin,  or  to  make 
it  no  lonojer  leojal  tender. 

The  fact  that  the  currency  of  coins  itself  effects  a  separation 
between  their  nominal  and  their  real  weight,  creating  a  dis- 
tinction between  them  as  mere  pieces  of  metal  on  the  one  hand, 
and  as  coins  with  a  definite  function  on  the  other — this  fact 
implies  the  latent  possibility  of  replacing  metallic  coins  by 
tokens  of  some  other  material,  by  symbols  serving  the  same 
purposes  as  coins.  The  practical  difficulties  in  the  way  of 
coining  extremely  minute  quantities  of  gold  or  silver,  and  the 
circumstance  that  at  first  the  less  precious  metal  is  used  as  a 
measure  of  value  instead  of  the  more  precious,  copper  instead 
of  silver,  silver  instead  of  gold,  and  that  the  less  precious 
circulates  as  money  until  dethroned  by  the  more  precious — all 
these  facts  explain  the  parts  historically  played  by  silver  and 

which  the  English  Government  coins  gratuitously,  the  following  opinion  of  Sir 
Dudley  North:  "Silver  and  gold,  like  other  commodities,  have  their  ebbings  and 
Sowings.  Upon  the  arrival  of  quantities  from  Spain  .  .  .  it  is  carried  into  the 
Tower,  and  coined.  Not  long  after  there  will  come  a  demand  for  bullion  to  be 
exported  again.  If  there  is  none,  but  all  happens  to  be  in  coin,  what  then  ?  Melt  it 
down  again ;  there's  no  loss  in  it,  for  the  coining  costs  the  owner  nothing.  Thus  the 
nation  has  been  abused,  and  made  to  pay  for  the  twisting  of  straw  for  asses  to  eat. 
If  the  merchant  were  made  to  pay  the  price  of  the  coinage,  he  would  not  have  sent  his 
fiilver  to  the  Tower  without  consideration ;  and  coined  money  would  always  keep  a  value 
above  uncoined  silver."  (North,  1.  c,  p.  18.)  North  was  himself  one  of  the  foremost 
merchants  in  the  reign  of  Charles  II. 


I02  Capitalist  Prodtution. 

copper  tokens  as  substitutes  for  gold  coins.  Silver  and  copper 
tokens  take  the  place  of  gold  in  those  regions  of  the  circulation 
where  coins  pass  from  hand  to  hand  most  rapidly,  and  arc 
subject  to  the  maximum  amount  of  wear  and  tear.  This  occurs 
where  sales  and  purchases  on  a  very  small  scale  are  continually 
happening.  In  order  to  prevent  these  satellites  from  establish- 
ing themselves  permanent^  in  the  place  of  gold,  positive 
enactments  determine  the  extent  to  which  they  must  be  com- 
pulsorily  received  as  payment  instead  of  gold.  The  particular 
tracks  pursued  by  the  different  species  of  coin  in  currency,  run 
naturally  into  each  other.  The  tokens  keep  company  with 
gold,  to  pay  fractional  parts  of  the  smallest  gold  coin  ;  gold  is,, 
on  the  one  hand,  constantly  pouring  into  retail  circulation,  and 
on  the  other  hand  is  as  constantly  being  thrown  out  again  by 
beinor  changed  into  tokens.  ^ 

o  o 

The  weight  of  metal  in  the  silver  and  copper  tokens  is^ 
arbitrarily  fixed  by  law.  When  in  currency,  they  wear  away 
even  more  rapidly  than  gold  coins.  Hence  their  functions  arc 
totally  independent  of  their  weight,  and  consequently  of  all 
value.  The  function  of  gold  as  coin  becomes  completely  inde- 
pendent of  the  metallic  value  of  that  gold.  Therefore  things 
that  are  relatively  without  value,  such  as  paper  notes,  can 
serve  as  coins  in  its  place.  This  purely  symbolic  character  is^ 
to  a  certain  extent  masked  in  metal  tokens.  In  paper  money 
it  stands  out  plainly.  In  fact,  ce  n'est  que  le  premier  pas  qui 
coute. 

We  allude  here  only  to  inconvertible  paper  money  issued  by 
the  State  and  having  compulsory  circulation.  It  has  its 
immediate  origin  in  the  metallic  currency.  Money  based  upon 
credit  implies  on  the  other  hand  conditions,  which,  from  our 

1  "  If  silver  never  exceed  what  is  wanted  for  the  smaller  payments,  it  cannot  be 
collected  in  sufficient  quantities  for  the  larger  payments  .  .  .  the  use  of  gold  in 
the  main  payments  necessarily  implies  also  its  use  in  the  retail  trade  :  those  who 
have  gold  coin  ojffering  them  for  small  purchases,  and  receiving  with  the  commodity 
purchased  a  balance  of  silver  in  return  ;  by  which  means  the  surplus  of  silver  that 
would  otherwise  encumber  the  retail  dealer,  is  drawn  off  and  dispersed  into  general 
circulation.  But  if  there  is  as  much  silver  as  will  transact  the  small  payments  in- 
dependent of  gold,  the  retail  trader  must  then  receive  silver  for  small  purchases ; 
and  it  must  of  necessity  accumulate  in  his  hands."  (David  Buchanan.  "  Inquiry  inta 
the  Taxation  and  Commercial  Policy  of  Great  Britain."  Edinburgh,  1844,  pp.  248,  249. > 


Money y  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,     103 

standpoint  of  the  simple  circulation  of  commodities,  are  as  yet 
totally  unknown  to  us.  But  we  may  affirm  this  much,  that 
just  as  true  paper  money  takes  its  rise  in  the  function  of  money 
as  the  circulating  medium,  so  money  based  upon  credit  takes 
root  spontaneously  in  the  function  of  money  as  the  means  of 
payment.^ 

The  State  puts  in  circulation  bits  of  paper  on  which  their 
various  denominations,  say  £1,  £5,  &ic.,  are  printed.  In  so  far 
as  they  actually  take  the  place  of  gold  to  the  same  amount, 
their  movement  is  subject  to  the  laws  that  regulate  the  currency 
of  money  itself.  A  law  peculiar  to  the  circulation  of  paper 
money  can  spring  up  only  from  the  proportion  in  which  that 
paper  money  represents  gold.  Such  a  law  exists  ;  stated 
simply,  it  is  as  follows :  the  issue  of  paper  money  must  not 
exceed  in  amount  the  gold  (or  silver  as  the  case  may  be)  which 
would  actually  circulate  if  not  replaced  by  symbols.  Now  the 
quantity  of  gold  which  the  circulation  can  absorb,  constantly 
liuctuates  about  a  given  level.  Still,  the  mass  of  the  circulating 
medium  in  a  given  country  never  sinks  below  a  certain 
minimum  easily  ascertained  by  actual  experience.  The  fact 
that  this  minimum  mass  continually  undergoes  changes  in  its 
constituent  parts,  or  that  the  pieces  of  gold  of  which  it  consists 
are  being  constantly  replaced  by  fresh  ones,  causes  of  course  no 
change  either  in  its  amount  or  in  the  continuity  of  its  circula- 
tion. It  can  therefore  be  replaced  by  paper  symbols.  If,  on 
the  other  hand,  all  the  conduits  of  circulation  were  to-day  filled 
with  paper  money  to  the  full  extent  of  their  capacity  for 

1  The  mandarin  Wan-mao-in,  the  Chinese  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  took  it  into 
his  head  one  day  to  lay  before  the  Son  of  Heaven  a  proposal  that  secretly  aimed  at 
converting  the  assignats  of  the  empire  into  convertible  bank  notes.  The  assignats 
Committee,  in  its  report  of  April,  1854,  gives  him  a  severe  snubbing.  Whether  he 
also  received  the  traditional  drubbing  with  bamboos  is  not  stated.  The  concluding 
part  of  the  report  is  as  follows  : — ' '  The  Committee  has  carefully  examined  his  pro- 
posal and  finds  that  it  is  entirely  in  favour  of  the  merchants,  and  that  no  advantage 
will  result  to  the  crown."  (Arbeiten  der  Kaiserlich  Russischen  Gcsandtschaft  zu 
Peking  iiber  China.  Aus  dem  Eussischen  von  Dr.  K.  Abel  und  F.  A.  Mecklenburg. 
Erster  Band.  Berlin,  1858,  pp.  47,  59.)  In  his  evidence  before  the  Committee  of  the 
House  of  Lords  on  the  Bank  Acts,  a  governor  of  the  Bank  of  England  says,  with 
regard  to  the  abrasion  of  gold  coins  during  currency  :  "  Every  year  a  fresh  class  of 
sovereigns  becomes  too  light.  The  class  which  one  year  passes  with  full  weight, 
loses  enougli  by  wear  and  tear  to  draw  the  scales  next  year  against  it."  (House  of 
Lords'  Committee,  1848,  n.  429.) 


T04  Capitalist  Production. 

absorbing  money,  they  might  to-morrow  be  overflowing  in 
consequence  of  a  fluctuation  in  the  circulation  of  commodities. 
There  would  no  longer  be  any  standard.  If  the  paper  money 
exceed  its  proper  limit,  which  is  the  amount  in  gold  coins  of 
the  like  denomination  that  can  actually  be  current,  it  would, 
apart  from  the  danger  of  falling  into  general  disrepute,  re- 
present only  that  quantity  of  gold,  which,  in  accordance  with 
the  laws  of  the  circulation  of  commodities,  is  required,  and  is 
alone  capable  of  being  represented  by  paper.  If  the  quantity 
of  paper  money  issued  be  double  what  it  ought  to  be,  then,  as 
a  matter  of  fact,  £1  would  be  the  money-name  not  of  \  of  an 
ounce,  but  of  \  of  an  ounce  of  gold.  The  eftect  would  be  the 
same  as  if  an  alteration  had  taken  place  in  the  function  of  gold 
as  a  standard  of  prices.  Those  values  that  were  previously 
expressed  by  the  price  of  £1  would  now  be  expressed  by  the 
price  of  £2. 

Paper-money  is  a  token  representing  gold  or  money.  The 
relation  between  it  and  the  values  of  commodities  is  this,  that 
the  latter  are  ideally  expressed  in  the  same  quantities  of  gold 
that  are  symbolically  represented  by  the  paper.  Only  in  so 
far  as  paper-money  represents  gold,  which  like  all  other  com- 
modities has  value,  is  it  a  symbol  of  value.  ^ 

Finally,  some  one  may  ask  why  gold  is  capable  of  being 
replaced  by  tokens  that  have  no  value?  But,  as  we  have 
already  seen,  it  is  capable  of  being  so  replaced  only  in  so  far 
as  it  functions  exclusively  as  coin,  or  as  the  circulating- 
medium,  and  as  nothing  else.  Now,  money  has  other  functions 
besides  this  one,  and  the  isolated  function  of  serving  as  the 
mere   circulating   medium   is    not   necessarily   the   only   one 

1  The  following  passage  from  Fullarton  shows  the  want  of  clearness  on  the  part  of 
even  the  best  writers  on  money,  in  their  comprehension  of  its  various  functions : 
"That,  as  far  as  concerns  our  domestic  exchanges,  all  the  monetary  functions  which 
are  usually  performed  by  gold  and  silver  coins,  may  be  performed  as  effectually  by  a 
circulation  of  inconvertible  notes,  having  no  value  but  that  factitious  and  conven- 
tional value  they  derive  from  the  law,  is  a  fact  which  admits,  I  conceive,  of  no 
denial.  Value  of  this  description  may  be  made  to  answer  all  the  purposes  of  intrinsic 
value,  and  supersede  even  the  necessity  for  a  standard,  provided  only  the  quantity 
of  issues  be  kept  under  due  limitation."  (Fullarton:  " Regulation  of  Currencies," 
London,  1844,  p.  21.)  Because  the  commodity  that  serves  as  money  is  capable 
of  being  replaced  in  circulation  by  mere  symbols  of  value,  therefore  its  functions  as 
a  measure  of  value  and  a  standard  of  prices  are  declared  to  be  superfluous  ! 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.    105 

attached  to  gold  coin,  although  this  is  the  case  with  those 
abraded  coins  that  continue  to  circulate.  Each  piece  of  money 
is  a  mere  coin,  or  means  of  circulation,  only  so  long  as  it  actually 
circulates.  But  this  is  just  the  case  with  that  minimum  mass 
of  gold,  which  is  capable  of  being  replaced  by  paper-money. 
That  mass  remains  constantly  within  the  sphere  of  circulation, 
continually  functions  as  a  circulating  medium,  and  exists  ex- 
clusively for  that  purpose.  Its  movement  therefore  represents 
nothing  but  the  continued  alternation  of  the  inverse  phases  of 
the  metamorphosis  C — M — C,  phases  in  which  commodities  con- 
front their  value-forms,  only  to  disappear  again  immediately. 
The  independent  existence  of  the  exchange  value  of  a  com- 
modity is  here  a  transient  apparition,  by  means  of  which  the 
commodity  is  immediately  replaced  by  another  commodity. 
Hence,  in  this  process  which  continually  makes  money  pass 
from  hand  to  hand,  the  mere  symbolical  existence  of  money 
suffices.  Its  functional  existence  absorbs,  so  to  say,  its 
material  existence.  Being  a  transient  and  objective  reflex  of 
the  prices  of  commodities,  it  serves  only  as  a  symbol  of  itself, 
and  is  therefore  capable  of  being  replaced  by  a  token.  ^  One 
thing  is,  however,  requisite ;  this  token  must  have  an  objective 
social  validity  of  its  own,  and  this  the  paper  symbol  acquires 
by  its  forced  currency.  This  compulsory  action  of  the 
State  can  take  effect  only  within  that  inner  sphere  of  circula- 
tion which  is  co-terminous  with  the  territories  of  the  com- 
munity, but  it  is  also  only  within  that  sphere  that  money 
completely  responds  to  its  function  of  being  the  circulating 
medium,  or  becomes  coin. 

SECTION  3. — MONEY. 

The  commodity  that  functions  as  a  measure  of  value,  and, 

1  From  the  fact  that  gold  and  silver,  so  far  as  they  are  coins,  or  exclusively  serve 
as  the  medium  of  circulation,  become  mere  tokens  of  themselves,  Nicholas  Barbon 
deduces  the  right  of  Governments  "  to  raise  money,"  that  is,  to  give  to  the  weight  of 
silver  that  is  called  a  shilling  the  name  of  a  greater  weight,  such  as  a  crown  ;  and  so 
to  pay  creditors  shillings,  instead  of  crowns.  "  Money  does  wear  and  grow  lighter 
by  often  telling  over  ...  It  is  the  denomination  and  currency  of  the  money 
that  men  regard  in  bargaining,  and  not  the  quantity  of  silver  .  .  .  'Tis  tlie 
public  authority  upon  the  metal  that  makes  it  money."  (N.  Barbon,  1.  c,  pp.  29,  30, 
25.) 


io6  Capitalist  Production. 

cither  in  its  own  person  or  by  a  representative,  as  the  medium 
of  circulation,  is  money.  Gold  (or  silver)  is  therefore  money. 
It  functions  as  money,  on  the  one  hand,  when  it  has  to  be 
present  in  its  own  golden  person.  It  is  then  the  money -com- 
modity, neither  merely  ideal,  as  in  its  function  of  a  measure 
of  value,  nor  capable  of  being  represented,  as  in  its  function  of 
circulating  medium.  On  the  other  hand,  it  also  functions  as 
money,  when  by  virtue  of  its  function,  whether  that  function 
be  performed  in  person  or  by  representative,  it  congeals  into  the 
sole  form  of  value,  the  only  adequate  form  of  existence  of 
exchange- value,  in  opposition  to  use-value,  represented  by  all 
other  commodities. 

a.  Hoarding. 

The  continual  movement  in  circuits  of  the  two  antithetical 
metamorphoses  of  commodities,  or  the  never  ceasing  alternation 
of  sale  and  purchase,  is  reflected  in  the  restless  currency  of 
money,  or  in  the  function  that  money  performs  of  a  perpetuum 
mobile  of  circulation.  But  so  soon  as  the  series  of  metamor- 
phoses is  interrupted,  so  soon  as  sales  are  not  supplemented  by 
subsequent  purchases,  money  ceases  to  be  mobilised ;  it  is  trans- 
formed, as  Boisguillebert  says,  from  "  meuble "  into  "  im- 
meuble,"  from  movable  into  immovable,  from  coin  into 
money. 

With  the  very  earliest  development  of  the  circulation  of 
commodities,  there  is  also  developed  the  necessity,  and  the 
passionate  desire,  to  hold  fast  the  product  of  the  first  metamor- 
phosis. This  product  is  the  transformed  shape  of  the  com- 
modity, or  its  gold-chrysalis.  ^  Commodities  are  thus  sold  not 
for  the  purpose  of  buying  others,  but  in  order  to  replace  their 
commodity-form  by  their  money-form.  From  being  the  mere 
means  of  effecting  the  circulation  of  commodities,  this  change 
of  form  becomes  the  end  and  aim.  The  changed  form  of  the 
commodity  is  thus  prevented  from  functioning  as  its  uncondi- 
tionally alienable  form,  or  as  its  merely  transient  money-form. 

1  "  Une  richesse  en  argent  n'est  que  .  .  .  richesse  en  productions,  converties 
en  argent."  (Mercier  de  la  Eiviere,  1.  c.)  "Une  valeur  en  productions  n'a  fait  que 
changer  de  forme."    (Id.,  p.  486.) 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,    loj 

The  money  becomes  petrified  into  a  hoard,  and  the  seller 
becomes  a  hoarder  of  monej^-. 

In  the  early  stages  of  the  circulation  of  commodities,  it  is 
the  surplus  use-values  alone  that  are  converted  into  money. 
Gold  and  silver  thus  become  of  themselves  social  expressions 
for  superfluity  or  wealth.  This  naive  form  of  hoarding  be- 
comes perpetuated  in  those  communities  in  which  the  tra- 
ditional mode  of  production  is  carried  on  for  the  supply  of  a 
fixed  and  limited  circle  of  home  wants.  It  is  thus  with  the 
people  of  Asia,  and  particularly  of  the  East  Indies.  Vanderlint, 
who  fancies  that  the  prices  of  commodities  in  a  country  are 
determined  by  the  quantity  of  gold  and  silver  to  be  found  in 
it,  asks  himself  why  Indian  commodities  are  so  cheap.  An- 
swer :  Because  the  Hindoos  bury  their  money.  From  1602  to 
1734,  he  remarks,  the}^  buried  150  millions  of  pounds  sterling 
of  silver,  which  originally  came  from  America  to  Europe.^  In 
the  10  years  from  1856  to  1866,  England  exported  to  India 
and  China  £120,000,000  in  silver,  which  had  been  received  in 
exchange  for  Australian  gold.  Most  of  the  silver  exported  to 
China  makes  its  way  to  India. 

As  the  production  of  commodities  further  developes,  every 
producer  of  commodities  is  compelled  to  make  sure  of  the 
nexus  rerum  or  the  social  pledge.^  His  wants  are  constantly 
making  themselves  felt,  and  necessitate  the  continual  purchase 
of  other  people's  commodities,  while  the  production  and  sale  of 
his  own  goods  require  time,  and  depend  upon  circumstances. 
In  order  then  to  be  able  to  buy  without  selling,  he  must  have 
sold  previously  without  buying.  This  operation,  conducted 
on  a  general  scale,  appears  to  imply  a  contradiction.  But  the 
precious  metals  at  the  sources  of  their  production  are  directly 
exchanged  for  other  commodities.  And  here  we  have  sales 
(by  the  owners  of  commodities)  without  purchases  (by  the 
owners  of  gold  or  silver).^      And  subsequent  sales,  by  other 

1  "  'Tis  by  this  practice  they  keep  all  their  goods  and  manufactures  at  such  low- 
rates."    (Vanderlint,  1.  c,  p.  96.) 

'-*  "Money  .  .  .  is  a  pledge."  { John  Bellers :  "  Essays  about  the  Poor,  Manufacturers, 
Trade,  Plantations,  and  Immorality,"  Lond.,  1699,  p.  13.) 

3  A  purchase,  in  a  "  categorical "  sense,  implies  that  gold  and  silver  are  already  the 
converted  form  of  commodities,  or  the  product  of  a  sale. 


io8  Capitalist  Production, 

producers,  unfoUowed  by  purchases,  merely  bring  about  the 
distribution  of  the  newly  produced  precious  metals  among  all 
the  owners  of  commodities.  In  this  way,  all  along  the  line  of 
exchange,  hoards  of  gold  and  silver  of  varied  extent  are  ac- 
cumulated. With  the  possibility  of  holding  and  storing  up 
exchange  value  in  the  shape  of  a  particular  commodity,  arises 
also  the  greed  for  gold.  Along  with  the  extension  of  circula- 
tion, increases  the  power  of  money,  that  absolutely  social  form 
of  wealth  ever  ready  for  use.  "  Gold  is  a  wonderful  thing ! 
Whoever  possesses  it  is  lord  of  all  he  wants.  By  means  of 
gold  one  can  even  get  souls  into  Paradise."  (Columbus  in  his 
letter  from  Jamaica,  1503.)  Since  gold  does  not  disclose  what 
has  been  transformed  into  it,  everj^thing,  commodity  or  not, 
is  convertible  into  gold.  Everything  becomes  saleable  and 
buyable.  The  circulation  becomes  the  great  social  retort  into 
which  everything  is  thrown,  to  come  out  aga^in  as  a  gold- 
crystal.  Not  even  are  the  bones  of  saints,  and  still  less  are 
more  delicate  res  sacrosanctse  extra  commercium  hominum 
able  to  withstand  this  alchemy.^  Just  as  every  qualitative 
difference  between  commodities  is  extinguished  in  money,  so 
money,  on  its  side,  like  the  radical  leveller  that  it  is,  does 
away  with  all  distinctions.^     But  money  itself  is  a  commodity, 

1  Henry  III.,  most  Christian  king  of  France,  robbed  cloisters  of  their  relics,  and 
turned  them  into  money.  It  is  well  known  what  part  the  despoiling  of  the  Delphic 
Temple,  by  the  Phocians,  played  in  the  history  of  Greece.  Temples  with  the  ancients 
served  as  the  dwellings  of  the  gods  of  commodities..  They  were  "sacred  banks. "  With 
the  Phoenicians,  a  trading  people  par  excellence,  money  was  the  transmuted  shape  of 
everything.  It  was,  therefore,  quite  in  order  that  the  virgins,  who,  at  the  feast  of 
the  Goddess  of  Love,  gave  themselves  up  to  strangers,  should  offer  to  the  goddess  the 
piece  of  money  they  received. 

2  "  Gold,  yellow,  glittering,  precious  gold  ! 

Thus  much  of  this,  will  make  black  white ;  foul,  fair  ; 

Wrong  right ;  base,  noble  ;  old,  young ;  coward,  valiant. 

.  .  .  What  this,  you  gods  ?    Why,  this 

Will  lug  your  priests  and  servants  from  your  sides  ; 

Pluck  stout  men's  pillows  from  below  their  heads ; 

This  yellow  slave 

Will  knit  and  break  religions ;  bless  the  accurs'd  ; 

Make  the  hoar  leprosy  ador'd ;  place  thieves. 

And  give  them  title,  knee  and  approbation, 

With  senators  on  the  bench  ;  this  is  it, 

That  makes  the  wappen'd  widow  wed  again : 

Come  damned  earth, 

Thou  common  whore  of  mankind." 

(Shakespeare  :  Timon  of  -Athers.) 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,     109 

an  external  object,  capable  of  becoming  the  private  property 
of  any  individual.  Thus  social  power  becomes  the  private 
power  of  private  persons.  The  ancients  therefore  denounced 
money  as  subversive  of  the  economical  and  moral  order  of 
things.^  Modern  society,  which,  soon  after  its  birth,  pulled 
Plutus  by  the  hair  of  his  head  from  the  bowels  of  the  earth,  ^ 
greets  gold  as  its  Holy  Grail,  as  the  glittering  incarnation  of 
the  very  principle  of  its  own  life. 

A  commodity,  in  its  capacity  of  a  use- value,  satisfies  a 
particular  want,  and  is  a  particular  element  of  material  wealth. 
But  the  value  of  a  commodity  measures  the  degree  of  its 
attraction  for  all  other  elements  of  material  wealth,  and  there- 
fore measures  the  social  wealth  of  its  owner.  To  a  barbarian 
owner  of  commodities,  and  even  to  a  West-European  peasant, 
value  is  the  same  as  value-form,  and  therefore,  to  him  the 
increase  in  his  hoard  of  gold  and  silver  is  an  increase  in  value. 
It  is  true  that  the  value  of  money  varies,  at  one  time  in  con- 
sequence of  a  variation  in  its  own  value,  at  another,  in 
consequence  of  a  change  in  the  values  of  commodities.  But 
this,  on  the  one  hand,  does  not  prevent  200  ounces  of  gold  from 
still  containing  more  value  than  100  ounces,  nor,  on  the  other 
hand,  does  it  hinder  the  actual  metallic  form  of  this  article 
from  continuing  to  be  the  universal  equivalent  form  of  all  other 
commodities,  and  the  immediate  social  incarnation  of  all 
human  labour.  The  desire  after  hoarding  is  in  its  very  nature 
unsatiable.  In  its  qualitative  aspect,  or  formally  considered, 
money  has  no  bounds  to  its  efficacy,  i.e.^  it  is  the  universal  re- 
presentative of  material  wealth,  because  it  is  directly  convertible 
into  any  other  commodity.  But,  at  the  same  time,  every  actual 
sum  of  money  is  limited  in  amount,  and,  therefore,  as  a  means 

^    "  Ol'^sv  yctf  av^puTOKTiv  elov  apyvpos 

Kkkov  vofjcifffAU  i^Xuffri'ToVTO  xal  -roXn; 
Ilophi,  ToV  eiv'^pas  i^avia-rfj'rtv  'h'ofjt.uv. 
ToV  ixhthxTKii  xkI  •Ttt.ptt.XXdfftni  (ppivas 
Xp*i(rrcis  'Tpos  alff^pcL  avdpuTon  ix*'*i 
Kal  ^avTOi  ^pyev  ^vctr'sfiiieiv  it^ivai.''' 

(Sophocles,  Antigone). 

'   "  'EX-ri^ova-rif  riji  ^Xiovt^ias  dvd^nv   Ix,   rav  f/.v^uv  rrji    yijs  avrov   rov    Uy.ovruvct" 

(Athen.  Deipnos.) 


no  Capitalist  Prodtiction. 

of  purchasing,  has  only  a  limited  efficacy.  This  antagonism 
between  the  quantitative  limits  of  money  and  its  qualitative 
boundlessness,  continually  acts  as  a  spur  to  the  hoarder  in  his 
Sisyphus-like  labour  of  accumulating.  It  is  with  him  as  it  is 
with  a  conqueror  who  sees  in  every  new  country  annexed,  only 
a  new  boundary. 

In  order  that  gold  may  be  held  as  money,  and  made  to  form 
a  hoard,  it  must  be  prevented  from  circulating,  or  from  trans- 
forming itself  into  a  means  of  enjoyment.  The  hoarder, 
therefore,  makes  a  sacrifice  of  the  lusts  of  the  flesh  to  his  gold 
fetish.  He  acts  in  earnest  up  to  the  Gospel  of  abstention.  On 
the  other  hand,  he  can  withdraw  from  circulation  no  more  than 
what  he  has  thrown  into  it  in  the  shape  of  commodities.  The 
more  he  produces,  the  more  he  is  able  to  sell.  Hard  work, 
saving,  and  avarice,  are,  therefore,  his  three  cardinal  virtues, 
and  to  sell  much  and  buy  little  the  sum  of  his  political 
economy.  ^ 

By  the  side  of  the  gross  form  of  a  hoard,  we  find  also  its 
aesthetic  form  in  the  possession  of  gold  and  silver  articles.  This 
grows  with  the  wealth  of  civil  society.  *'  Soyons  riches  ou 
paraissons  riches  "  (Diderot).  In  this  way  there  is  created,  on  the 
one  hand,  a  constantly  extending  market  for  gold  and  silver, 
unconnected  with  their  functions  as  money,  and,  on  the  other 
hand,  a  latent  source  of  supply,  to  which  recourse  is  had 
principally  in  times  of  crisis  and  social  disturbance. 

Hoarding  serves  various  purposes  in  the  economy  of  the 
metallic  circulation.  Its  first  function  arises  out  of  the  conditions 
to  which  the  currency  of  gold  and  silver  coins  is  subject.  We 
have  seen  how,  along  with  the  continual  fluctuations  in  the 
extent  and  rapidity  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  and  in 
their  prices,  the  quantity  of  money  current  unceasingly  ebbs 
and  flows.  This  mass  must,  therefore,  be  capable  of  expansion 
and  contraction.  At  one  time  money  must  be  attracted  in 
order  to  act  as  circulating  coin,  at  another,  circulating  coin  must 
be  repelled  in  order  to  act  again  as  more  or  less  stagnant  money. 

1  "Accrescere  quanto  piu  si  puo  il  numero  de' venditori  d'ogni  merce,  diminuere 
quanto  pid  si  puo  il  numero  dei  compratori,  questi  sono  i  cardini  sui  quail  si  raggirano 
tutte  le  operazioni  di  economia  politica."  (Verri,  l.c.  p.  52.) 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,     1 1 1 

In  order  that  the  mass  of  money,  actually  current,  may  con- 
stantly saturate  the  absorbing  power  of  the  circulation,  it  is 
necessary  that  the  quantity  of  gold  and  silver  in  a  country  be 
greater  than  the  quantity  required  to  function  as  coin.  This 
condition  is  fulfilled  by  money  taking  the  form  of  hoards. 
These  reserves  serve  as  conduits  for  the  supply  or  withdrawal 
of  money  to  or  from  the  circulation,  which  in  this  way  never 
overflows  its  banks.  ^ 

h.  Means  of  Payment 

In  the  simple  form  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  hitherto 
•considered,  we  found  a  given  value  always  presented  to  us  in 
a  double  shape,  as  a  commodity  at  one  pole,  as  money  at  the 
opposite  pole.  The  owners  of  commodities  came  therefore  into 
contact  as  the  respective  representatives  of  what  were  already 
equivalents.  But  with  the  development  of  circulation,  condi- 
tions arise  under  which  the  alienation  of  commodities  becomes 
separated,  by  an  interval  of  time,  from  the  realisation  of  their 
prices.  It  will  be  sufficient  to  indicate  the  most  simple  of 
these  conditions.  One  sort  of  article  requires  a  longer,  another 
^  shorter  time  for  its  production.  Again,  the  production  of 
different  commodities  depends  on  different  seasons  of  the  year. 
One  sort  of  commodity  may  be  born  on  its  own  market  place, 
another  has  to  make  a  long  journey  to  market.  Commodity- 
owner  No.  1,  may  therefore  be  ready  to  sell,  before  No.  2  is 
ready  to  buy.     When  the  same  transactions  are  continually 

1  "  There  is  required  for  carrying  on  the  trade  of  the  nation  a  determinate  sum  of 
•specifick  money,  which  varies,  and  is  sometimes  more,  sometimes  less,  as  the  circum- 
stances we  are  in  require.  .  .  .  This  ebbing  and  flowing  of  money  supplies  and 
accommodates  itself,  without  any  aid  of  Politicians.  .  .  .  The  buckets  work 
alternately ;  when  money  is  scarce,  bullion  is  coined ;  when  bullion  is  scarce,  money 
is  melted."  (Sir  D.  North,  1.  c.  Postscript,  p.  3.)  John  Stuart  Mill,  who  for  a  long  time 
was  an  oflBcial  of  the  East  India  Company,  confirms  the  fact  that  in  India  silver  orna- 
ments still  continue  to  perform  directly  the  functions  of  a  hoard.  The  silver 
ornaments  are  brought  out  and  coined  when  there  is  a  high  rate  of  interest,  and  go 
back  again  when  the  rate  of  interest  falls.  (J.  S.  Mill's  Evidence.  "  Reports  on 
Bank  Acts,"  1857,  2084.)  According  to  a  Parliamentary  document  of  1864,  on  the  gold 
And  silver  import  and  export  of  India,  the  import  of  gold  and  silver  in  1863  exceeded 
the  export  by  £19,367,764.  During  the  8  years  immediately  preceding  1864,  the 
excess  of  imports  over  exports  of  the  precious  metals  amounted  to  £109,652,917. 
During  this  century  far  more  than  £200,000,000  has  been  coined  in  India. 


112  Capitalist  Production. 

repeated  between  the  same  persons,  the  conditions  of  sale  are 
regulated  in  accordance  with  the  conditions  of  production.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  use  of  a  given  commodity,  of  a  house,  for 
instance,  is  sold  (in  common  parlance,  let)  for  a  definite  period. 
Here,  it  is  only  at  the  end  of  the  term  that  the  buyer  has 
actually  received  the  use-value  of  the  commodity.  He  there- 
fore buys  it  before  he  pays  for  it.  The  vendor  sells  an  exist- 
ing commodity,  the  purchaser  buys  as  the  mere  representative 
of  money,  or  rather  of  future  money.  The  vendor  becomes  a 
creditor,  the  purchaser  becomes  a  debtor.  Since  the  metamor- 
phosis of  commodities,  or  the  development  of  their  value-form, 
appears  here  under  a  new  aspect,  money  also  acquires  a  fresh 
function ;  it  becomes  the  means  of  payment. 

The  character  of  creditor,  or  of  debtor,  results  here  from  the 
simple  circulation.  The  change  in  the  form  of  that  circulation 
stamps  buyer  and  seller  with  this  new  die.  At  first,  therefore, 
these  new  parts  are  just  as  transient  and  alternating  as  those  of 
seller  and  buyer,  and  are  in  turns  played  by  the  same  actors. 
But  the  opposition  is  not  nearly  so  pleasant,  and  is  far  more 
capable  of  crystallization.^  The  same  characters  can,  however, 
be  assumed  independently  of  the  circulation  of  commodities. 
The  class-struggles  of  the  ancient  world  took  the  form  chiefly 
of  a  contest  between  debtors  and  creditors,  which  in  Rome 
ended  in  the  ruin  of  the  plebeian  debtors.  They  were  dis- 
placed by  slaves.  In  the  middle-ages  the  contest  ended  with 
the  ruin  of  the  feudal  debtors,  who  lost  their  political  power 
together  with  the  economical  basis  on  which  it  was  established. 
Nevertheless,  the  money  relation  of  debtor  and  creditor  that 
existed  at  these  two  periods  reflected  only  the  deeper-lying 
antagonism  between  the  general  economical  conditions  of 
existence  of  the  classes  in  question. 

Let  us  return  to  the  circulation  of  commodities.  The 
appearance  of  the  two  equivalents,  commodities  and  money,  at 
the  two  poles  of  the  process  of  sale,  has  ceased  to  be  simulta- 

1  The  following  shows  the  debtor  and  creditor  relations  existing  between  English 
traders  at  the  beginning  of  the  18th  century.  "  Such  a  spirit  of  cruelty  reigns  here 
in  England  among  the  men  of  trade,  that  is  not  to  be  met  with  in  any  other  society 
of  men,  nor  in  any  other  kingdom  of  the  world."  ("An  Essay  on  Credit  and  the 
Bankrupt  Act,"  Lond.,  1707,  p.  2.) 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities,     113 

neous.  The  money  functions  now,  first  as  a  measure  of  value 
in  the  determination  of  the  price  of  the  commodity  sold ;  the 
price  fixed  by  the  contract  measures  the  obligation  of  the 
debtor,  or  the  sum  of  money  that  he  has  to  pay  at  a  fixed 
date.  Secondly,  it  serves  as  an  ideal  means  of  purchase. 
Although  existing  only  in  the  promise  of  the  buyer  to  pay,  it 
causes  the  commodity  to  change  hands.  It  is  not  before  the 
day  fixed  for  payment  that  the  means  of  payment  actually 
steps  into  circulation,  leaves  the  hand  of  the  buyer  for  that  of 
the  seller.  The  circulating  medium  was  transformed  into  a 
hoard,  because  the  process  stopped  short  after  the  first  phase, 
because  the  converted  shape  of  the  commodity,  viz.,  the  money, 
was  withdrawn  from  circulation.  The  means  of  payment 
enters  the  circulation,  but  only  after  the  commodity  has  left 
it.  The  money  is  no  longer  the  means  that  brings  about  the 
process.  It  only  brings  it  to  a  close,  by  stepping  in  as  the 
absolute  form  of  existence  of  exchange  value,  or  as  the 
universal  commodity.  The  seller  turned  his  commodity  into 
money,  in  order  thereby  to  satisfy  some  want ;  the  hoarder  did 
the  same  in  order  to  keep  his  commodity  in  its  money-shape, 
and  the  debtor  in  order  to  be  able  to  pay ;  if  he  do  not  pay, 
his  goods  will  be  sold  by  the  sheriff".  The  value-form  of  com- 
modities, money,  is  therefore  now  the  end  and  aim  of  a  sale, 
and  that  owing  to  a  social  necessity  springing  out  of  the 
process  of  circulation  itself. 

The  buyer  converts  money  back  into  commodities  before  he 
has  turned  commodities  into  money :  in  other  words,  he  achieves 
the  second  metamorphosis  of  commodities  before  the  first.  The 
seller's  commodity  circulates,  and  realises  its  price,  but  only  in 
the  shape  of  a  legal  claim  upon  money.  It  is  converted  into  a 
use-value  before  it  has  been  converted  into  money.  The 
completion  of  its  first  metamorphosis  follows  only  at  a  later 
period.^ 

1  It  will  be  seen  from  the  following  quotation  from  my  book  which  appeared  ia 
1859,  why  I  take  no  notice  in  the  text  of  an  opposite  form  :  * 'Contrariwise,  in  the  pro- 
cess M — C,  the  money  can  be  alienated  as  a  real  means  of  purchase,  and  in  that  way, 
the  price  of  the  commodity  can  be  realised  before  the  use-value  of  the  money  is 
realised  and  the  commodity  actually  delivered.  This  occurs  constantly  under  the 
every-day  form  of  pre-payments.    And  it  is  under  this  form,  that  the  EnglisL 

H 


114  Capitalist  Pi^oduciion. 

The  obligations  falling  due  within  a  given  period,  represent 
the  sum  of  the  prices  of  the  commodities,  the  sale  of  which 
gave  rise  to  those  obligations.  The  quantity  of  gold  necessary 
to  realise  this  sum,  depends,  in  the  first  instance,  on  the 
rapidity  of  currency  of  the  means  of  payment.  That  quantity 
is  conditioned  by  two  circumstances :  first  the  relations  be- 
tween debtors  and  creditors  form  a  sort  of  chain,  in  such  a  way 
that  A,  when  he  receives  money  from  his  debtor  B,  straight- 
way hands  it  over  to  C  his  creditor,  and  so  on ;  the  second 
circumstance  is  the  length  of  the  intervals  between  the 
different  due- days  of  the  obligations.  The  continuous  chain 
of  payments,  or  retarded  first  metamorphoses,  is  essentially 
different  from  that  interlacing  of  the  series  of  metamorphoses 
which  we  considered  on  a  former  page.  By  the  currency  of 
the  circulating  medium,  the  connexion  between  buyers  and 
sellers,  is  not  merely  expressed.  This  connexion  is  originated 
by,  and  exists  in,  the  circulation  alone.  Contrariwise,  the 
movement  of  the  means  of  payment  expresses  a  social  relation 
that  was  in  existence  long  before. 

The  fact  that  a  number  of  sales  take  place  simultaneously, 
and  side  by  side,  limits  the  extent  to  which  coin  can  be  re- 
placed by  the  rapidity  of  currency.  On  the  other  hand,  this 
fact  is  a  new  lever  in  economising  the  means  of  payment.  In 
proportion  as  payments  are  concentrated  at  one  spot,  special 
institutions  and  methods  are  developed  for  their  liquidation. 
Such  in  the  middle  ages  were  the  virements  at  Lyons.  The 
debts  due  to  A  from  B,  to  B  from  C,  to  C  from  A,  and  so  on, 
have  only  to  be  confronted  with  each  other,  in  order  to  annul 
each  other  to  a  certain  extent  like  positive  and  negative 
quantities.  There  thus  remains  only  a  single  balance 
to  pay.  The  greater  the  amount  of  the  payments  concen- 
trated, the  less  is  this  balance  relatively  to  that  amount, 
and  the  less  is  the  mass  of  the  means  of  payment  in 
circulation. 

The  function  of  money  as  the  means  of  payment  implies  a 

government  purchases  opium  from  the  ryots  of  India.  ...  In  these  cases,  however,  the 
money  always  acts  as  a  means  of  purchase.  ...  Of  course  capital  also  is  ad- 
vanced in  the  shape  of  money.  .  .  .  This  point  of  view,  however,  does  not  fall 
within  the  horizon  of  simple  circulation."    ("Zur  Kj-itik."  &c.,  pp.  119,  120.) 


Money,  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.      115 

contradiction  without  a  terminus  medius.  In  so  far  as  the 
payments  balance  one  another,  money  functions  only  ideally 
as  money  of  account,  as  a  measure  of  value.  In  so  far  as  actual 
payments  have  to  be  made,  money  does  not  serve  as  a  circu- 
lating medium,  as  a  mere  transient  agent  in  the  interchange 
of  products,  but  as  the  individual  incarnation  of  social  labour, 
as  the  independent  form  of  existence  of  exchange  value,  as  the 
universal  commodity.  This  contradiction  comes  to  a  head  in 
those  phases  of  industrial  and  commercial  crises  which  are 
known  as  monetary  crises.^  Such  a  crisis  occurs  only  where 
the  ever-lengthening  chain  of  payments,  and  an  artificial  system 
of  settling  them,  has  been  fully  developed.  Whenever  there 
is  a  general  and  extensive  disturbance  of  this  mechanism,  no 
matter  what  its  cause,  money  becomes  suddenly  and  immedi- 
ately transformed,  from  its  merely  ideal  shape  of  money  of 
account,  into  hard  cash.  Profane  commodities  can  no  longer 
replace  it.  The  use-value  of  commodities  becomes  valueless, 
and  their  value  vanishes  in  the  presence  of  its  own  independent 
form.  On  the  eve  of  the  crisis,  the  bourgeois,  with  the  self- 
sufficiency  that  springs  from  intoxicating  prosperity,  declares 
money  to  be  a  vain  imagination.  Commodities  alone  are 
money.  But  now  the  cry  is  everywhere :  money  alone  is  a 
commodity !  As  the  hart  pants  after  fresh  water,  so  pants  his 
soul  after  money,  the  only  wealth.^  In  a  crisis,  the  antithesis 
between  commodities  and  their  value-form,  money,  becomes 
heightened  into  an  absolute  contradiction.  Hence,  in  such 
events,  the  form  under  which  money  appears  is  of  no  import- 

1  The  monetary  crisis  referred  to  in  the  text,  being  a  phase  of  every  crisis,  must  be 
clearly  distinguished  from  that  particular  form  of  crisis,  which  also  is  called  a  mone- 
tary crisis,  but  which  may  be  produced  by  itself  as  an  independent  phenomenon  in 
such  a  way  as  to  react  only  indirectly  on  industry  and  commerce.  The  pivot  of  these 
crises  is  to  be  found  in  moneyed  capital,  and  their  sphere  of  direct  action  is  there- 
fore the  sphere  of  that  capital,  viz.,  banking,  the  stock  exchange,  and  finance. 

2  ' '  The  sudden  reversion  from  a  system  of  credit  to  a  system  of  hard  cash  heaps 
theoretical  fright  on  top  of  the  practical  panic  ;  and  the  dealers  by  whose  agency 
circulation  is  affected,  shudder  before  the  impenetrable  mystery  in  which  their  own 
economical  relations  are  involved "  (Karl  Marx,  1.  c.  p.  126).  "The  poor  stand  still,  be- 
cause the  rich  have  no  money  to  emjjloy  them,  though  they  have  the  same  land  and 
hands  to  provide  victuals  and  clothes,  as  ever  they  had  ;  ,  .  .  which  is  the  true  Riches 
of  a  Nation,  and  not  the  money."  (John  Bellers :  "  Proposals  for  raising  a  Colledge 
of  Industry,"  Lond.  1695.  p.  3.) 


1 1 6  Capitalist  Production. 

ance.  The  money  famine  continues,  whether  payments  have 
to  be  made  in  gold  or  in  credit  money  such  as  bank-notes/ 

If  we  now  consider  the  sum  total  of  the  money  current  dur- 
ing a  given  period,  we  shall  find  that,  given  the  rapidity  of 
currency  of  the  circulating  medium  and  of  the  means  of  pay- 
ment, it  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  the  prices  to  be  realised,  plus 
the  sum  of  the  payments  falling  due,  minus  the  payments  that 
balance  each  other,  minus  finally  the  number  of  circuits  in 
which  the  same  piece  of  coin  serves  in  turn  as  means  of 
circulation  and  of  payment.  Hence,  even  when  prices,  rapidity 
of  currency,  and  the  extent  of  the  economy  in  payments,  are 
given,  the  quantity  of  money  current  and  the  mass  of  com- 
modities circulating  during  a  given  period,  such  as  a  day,  no 
longer  correspond.  Money  that  represents  commodities  long 
withdrawn  from  circulation,  continues  to  be  current.  Com- 
modities circulate,  whose  equivalent  in  money  will  not  appear 
on  the  scene  till  some  future  day.  Moreover,  the  debts  con- 
tracted each  day,  and  the  payments  falling  due  on  the  same 
day,  are  quite  incommensurable  quantities.^ 

Credit-money  springs  directly  out  of  the  function  of  money 
as  a  means  of  payment.     Certificates  of  the  debts  owing  for  the 

1  The  following  shows  how  such  times  are  exploited  by  the  "amis  du  commerce." 
' '  On  one  occasion  (1839)  an  old  grasping  banker  (in  the  city)  in  his  private  room  raised 
the  lid  of  the  desk  he  sat  over,  and  displayed  to  a  friend  rolls  of  banknotes,  saying 
with  intense  glee  there  were  £000,000  of  them,  they  were  held  to  make  money  tight, 
and  would  all  be  let  our  after  three  o'clock  on  the  same  day."  ("The  Theory  of 
Exchanges.  The  Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844."  Lond.  1864.  p.  81.)  The  Obsei-ver,  a 
semi-official  government  organ,  contained  the  following  paragraph  on  24th  April,  1864: 
'  *  Some  very  curious  rumours  are  current  of  the  means  which  have  been  resorted  to 

in  order  to  create  a  scarcity  of  Banknotes Questionable  as  it  would  seem,  to 

suppose  that  any  trick  of  the  kind  would  be  adopted,  the  report  has  been  so  universal 
that  it  really  deserves  mention." 

2  ' '  The  amount  of  purchases  or  contracts  entered  upon  during  the  course  of  any  given 
day,  will  not  affect  the  quantity  of  money  afloat  on  that  particular  day,  but,  in  the 
vast  majority  of  cases,  will  resolve  themselves  into  multifarious  drafts  upon  the 
quantity  of  money  which  may  be  afloat  at  subsequent  dates  more  or  less  distant. 
.  .  .  .  The  bills  granted  or  credits  opened,  to-day,  need  have  no  resemblance 
whatever,  cither  in  quantity,  amount,  or  duration,  to  those  granted  or  entered  upon 
to-morrow  or  next  day  ;  nay,  many  of  to-day's  bills,  and  credits,  when  due,  fall  in 
with  a  mass  of  liabilities  whose  origins  traverse  a  range  of  antecedent  dates  altogether 
indefinite,  bills  at  12,  6,  3  months  or  1  often  aggregating  together  to  swell  the  common 
liabilities  of  one  particular  day.  .  .  .  "  ("  The  Currency  Theory  Keviewed  ;  a 
letter  to  the  Sc(fttish  people."  By  a  Banker  in  England.  Edinburgh,  1845,  pp.  29,  30 
passim.) 


Mo7tey^  or  the  Circulation  of  Co7n7nodities,     \\^ 

purchased  commodities  circulate  for  the  purpose  of  transferring 
those  debts  to  others.  On  the  other  hand,  to  the  same  extent 
as  the  system  of  credit  is  extended,  so  is  the  function  of  money 
as  a  means  of  payment.  In  that  character  it  takes  various 
forms  peculiar  to  itself  under  which  it  makes  itself  at  home  in 
the  sphere  of  great  commercial  transactions.  Gold  and  silver 
coin,  on  the  other  hand,  are  mostly  relegated  to  the  sphere  of 
retail  trade.^ 

When  the  production  of  commodities  has  sufficiently  ex- 
tended itself,  money  begins  to  serve  as  the  means  of  payment 
beyond  the  sphere  of  the  circulation  of  commodities.  It 
becomes  the  commodity  that  is  the  universal  subject-matter  of 
all  contracts.^  Eents,  taxes,  and  such  like  payments  are 
transformed  from  payments  in  kind  into  money  payments.  To 
what  extent  this  transformation  depends  upon  the  general 
conditions  of  production,  is  shown,  to  take  one  example,  by  the 
fact  that  the  Eoman  Empire  twice  failed  in  its  attempt  to  levy 
all  contributions  in  money.  The  unspeakable  misery  of  the 
French  agricultural  population  under  Louis  XI Y.,  a  misery  so 
eloquently  denounced  by  Boisguillebert,  Marshal  Vauban,  and 
others,  was  due  not  only  to  the  weight  of  the  taxes,  but  also 


1  As  an  example  of  how  little  ready  money  is  required  in  true  commercial  opera- 
tions, I  give  below  a  statement  by  one  of  the  largest  London  houses  of  its  yearly 
receipts  and  payments.  Its  transactions  during  the  year  1856,  extending  to  many 
millions  of  pounds  sterling,  are  here  reduced  to  the  scale  of  one  million. 


Receipts. 

Paymrnts. 

Bankers'  and  Merchants'  Bills 

Bills  payable  after  date. 

-    £302,674 

payable  after  date, 

£533,596 

Cheques  on  London  Bankers, 

-      663,672 

Cheques     on     Bankers, 

&c.. 

Bank  of  England  Notes, 

22,743 

l^ayable  on  demand,   - 

357,715 

Gold,       -        -        -        - 

9:427 

Country  Notes, 

9,627 

Silver  and  Copper, 

1,484 

Bank  of  England  Notes, 

68,554 

Gold,      .... 

28,089 

Silver  and  Copper, 

1,486 

Post  Office  Orders, 

.  . 

933 

Total, 

Total, 

61,000,000 

£1,000,000 

•'  Report  from  the  Select  Committee  on  the  Bank  Acts,  July,  1858,"  p.  Ixxi. 

2  "The  course  of  trade  being  thus  turned,  from  exchanging  of  goods  for  goods,  or 
delivering  and  taking,  to  selling  and  paying,  all  the  bargains  .  .  .  are  now  stated 
upon  the  foot  of  a  Price  in  money."  ("  An  Essay  upon  Publick  Credit."  3rd  Ed. 
Lond.,  1710,  p.  8.) 


1 1 8  Capitalist  Prodtiction, 

to  the  conversion  of  taxevS  in  kind  into  money  taxes.^  In  Asia, 
on  the  other  hand,  the  fact  that  state  taxes  are  chiefly  composed 
of  rents  payable  in  kind,  depends  on  conditions  of  production 
that  are  reproduced  with  the  regularity  of  natural  phenomena. 
And  this  mode  of  payment  tends  in  its  turn  to  maintain  the 
ancient  form  of  production.  It  is  one  of  the  secrets  of  the  con- 
servation of  the  Ottoman  Empire.  If  the  foreign  trade,  forced 
upon  Japan  by  Europeans,  should  lead  to  the  substitution  of 
money  rents  for  rents  in  kind,  it  will  be  all  up  with  the 
exemplary  agriculture  of  that  country.  The  narrow  economical 
conditions  under  which  that  agriculture  is  carried  on,  will  be 
swept  away. 

In  every  country,  certain  days  of  the  year  become  by  habit 
recognised  settling  days  for  various  large  and  recurrent  pay- 
ments. These  dates  depend,  apart  from  other  revolutions  in  the 
wheel  of  reproduction,  on  conditions  clcsely  connected  with 
the  seasons.  They  also  regulate  the  dates  for  payments  that 
have  no  direct  connexion  with  the  circulation  of  commodities 
such  as  taxes,  rents,  and  so  on.  The  quantity  of  money  re- 
quisite to  make  the  payments,  falling  due  on  those  dates  all 
over  the  country,  causes  periodical,  though  merely  superficial, 
perturbations  in  the  economy  of  the  medium  of  payment.^ 

From  the  law  of  the  rapidity  of  currency  of  the  means  of 

1  "  L'argent ...  est  devenu  le  bourreau  de  toutes  choses."  Finance  is  the  "  alambic, 
qui  a  fait  evaporer  nne  quantite  effroyable  de  biens  et  de  denrees  pour  faire  ce  fatal 
precis."  "L'argent  declare  la  guerre  k  tout  le  genre  humain."  (Boisguillebert : 
"  Dissertation  sur  la  nature  des  richesses,  de  l'argent  et  des  tributs."  Edit.  Daire» 
Economistes  financiers.     Paris,  1843,  t.  i. ,  pp.  413,  419,  417. ) 

2  "  On  Whitsuntide,  1824,"  says  Mr  Craig  before  the  Commons'  Committee  of  182G, 
"there  was  such  an  immense  demand  for  notes  upon  the  banks  of  Edinburgh,  that 
by  11  o'clock  they  had  not  a  note  left  in  their  custody.  They  sent  round  to  all  the 
different  banks  to  borrow,  but  could  not  get  them,  and  many  of  the  transactions 
were  adjusted  by  slips  of  paper  only  ;  yet  by  three  o'clock  the  whole  of  the  notes 
were  returned  into  the  banks  from  which  they  had  issued  !  It  was  a  mere  transfer 
from  hand  to  hand."  Although  the  average,  effective  circulation  of  bank-notes  in 
Scotland  is  less  than  three  millions  sterling,  yet  on  certain  pay  days  in  the  year, 
every  single  note  in  the  possession  of  the  bankers,  amounting  in  the  whole  to  about 
£7,000,000,  is  called  into  activity.  On  these  occasions  the  notes  have  a  single  and 
specific  function  to  perform,  and  so  soon  as  they  have  performed  it,  they  flow  back 
into  the  various  banks  from  which  they  issued.  (See  John  Fullarton,  "  Regulation  of 
Currencies."  Lend :  1844,  p.  85  note).  In  explanation  it  should  be  stated, 
that  in  Scotland,  at  the  date  of  FuUarton's  work,  notes  and  not  cheques  were  used  to 
withdraw  deposits. 


Money ^  07""  the  Circtdation  of  Commodities.     119 

payment,  it  follows  that  the  quantity  of  the  means  of  pay- 
ment required  for  all  periodical  payments,  whatever  their 
source,  is  in  inverse  proportion  to  the  length  of  their  periods. 
The  development  of  money  into  a  medium  of  payment 
makes  it  necessary  to  accumulate  money  against  the  dates 
lixed  for  the  payment  of  the  sums  owing.  While  hoarding,  as 
a  distinct  mode  of  acquiring  riches,  vanishes  with  the  progress 
of  civil  society,  the  formation  of  reserves  of  the  means  of  pay- 
ment grows  with  that  progress. 

c.  Universal  Money. 

When  money  leaves  the  home  sphere  of  circulation,  it 
strips  off  the  local  garbs  which  it  there  assumes,  of  a  standard 
of  prices,  of  coin,  of  tokens,  and  of  a  symbol  of  value,  and  re- 
turns to  its  original  form  of  bullion.  In  the  trade  between  the 
markets  of  the  world,  the  value  of  commodities  is  expressed  so 
as  to  be  universally  recognised.  Hence  their  independent 
value-form  also,  in  these  cases,  confronts  them  under  the 
shape  of  universal  money.  It  is  only  in  the  markets  of  the 
world  that  money  acquires  to  the  full  extent  the  character  of  the 
commodity  whose  bodily  form  is  also  the  immediate  social  in- 
carnation of  human  labour  in  the  abstract.  Its  real  mode  of 
existence  in  this  sphere  adequately  corresponds  to  its  ideal 
concept. 

Within  the  sphere  of  home  circulation,  there  can  be  but  one 
commodity  which,  by  serving  as  a  measure  of  value,  becomes 
money.  In  the  markets  of  the  world  a  double  measure  of 
value  holds  sway,  gold  and  silver.^ 

1  To  the  question,  "If  there  were  occasion  to  raise  40  millions  p.  a.,  whether  the 
same  6  millions  (gold) .  .  .  would  suffice  for  such  revolutions  and  circulations  thereof, 
as  trade  requires,"  Petty  replies  in  his  usual  masterly  manner,  "  I  answer  yes  :  for  the 
expense  being  40  millions,  if  the  revolutions  were  in  such  short  circles,  viz.,  weekly, 
as  happens  among  poor  artizans  and  labourers,  who  receive  and  pay  every  Satui'day, 
then  \%  parts  of  1  million  of  money  would  answer  these  ends  ;  but  if  the  circles  be 
quarterly,  according  to  our  custom  of  paying  rent,  and  gathering  taxes,  then  10 
millions  were  requisite.  Wherefore,  supposing  payments  in  general  to  be  of  a  mixed 
circle  between  one  week  and  13,  then  add  10  millions  to  |§,  the  half  of  which  will 
be  5.3,  so  as  if  we  have  5|  millions  we  have  enough."  (William  Petty  :  "  Political 
Anatomy  of  Ireland."    1672.     Edit.  :  Lond.  1691,  pp.  13.  14.) 

2  Hence  the  absurdity  of  every  law  prescribing  that  the  banks  of  a  country  shall 
form  reserves  of  that  precious  metal  alone  which  circulates  at  home.    The  "  pleasant 


I20  Capitalist  Production. 

Money  of  the  world  serves  as  the  universal  medium  of 
payment,  as  the  universal  means  of  purchasing,  and  as  the 
universally  recognised  embodiment  of  all  wealth.  Its  function 
as  a  means  of  payment  in  the  settling  of  international  balances 
is  its  chief  one.  Hence  the  watchword  of  the  mercantilists, 
balance  of  trade.^  Gold  and  silver  serve  as  international  means 
of  purchasing  chiefly  and  necessarily  in  those  periods  when 
the  customary  equilibrium  in  the  interchange  of  products 
between  different  nations  is  suddenly  disturbed.  And  lastly, 
it  serves  as  the  universally  recognised  embodiment  of  social 
wealth,  whenever  the  question  is  not  of  buying  or  paying,  but 
of  transferring  wealth  from  one  country  to  another,  and  when- 
ever this  transference  in  the  form  of  commodities  is  rendered 
impossible,  either  by  special  conjunctures  in  the  markets,  or 
by  the  purpose  itself  that  is  intended.^ 

Just  as  every  country  needs  a  reserve  of  money  for  its  home 
circulation,  so,  too,  it  requires  one  for  external  circulation  in 

difficulties  "  thus  self -created  by  the  Bank  of  England,  are  well  known.  On  the 
subject  of  the  great  epochs  in  the  history  of  the  changes  in  the  relative  value  of  gold  and 
silver,  see  Karl  Marx,  1.  c.  p.  136  sq.  Sir  Eobert  Peel,  by  his  Bank  Act  of  1844,  sought 
to  tide  over  the  difficulty,  by  allowing  the  Bank  of  England  to  issue  notes  against 
silver  bullion,  on  condition  that  the  reserve  of  silver  should  never  exceed  more  than 
one-fourth  of  the  reserve  of  gold.  The  value  of  silver  being  for  that  purpose  estimated 
at  its  price  in  the  London  market. 

1  The  opponents,  themselves,  of  the  mercantile  system,  a  system  which  considered 
the  settlement  of  surplus  trade  balances  in  gold  and  silver  as  the  aim  of  international 
trade,  entirely  misconceived  the  functions  of  money  of  the  world.  I  have  shown  by 
the  example  of  Ricardo  in  what  way  their  false  conception  of  the  laws  that  regulate 
the  quantity  of  the  circulating  medium,  is  reflected  in  their  equally  false  conception 
of  the  international  movement  of  the  precious  metals  (1.  c.  pp.  150  sq.)  His 
erroneous  dogma:  "An  unfavourable  balance  of  trade  never  arises  but  from  a  re- 
dundant currency.  .  .  .  The  exportation  of  the  coin  is  caused  by  its  cheapness,  and 
is  not  the  effect,  but  the  cause  of  an  unfavourable  balance,"  already  occurs  inBarbon: 
"  The  Balance  of  Trade,  if  there  be  one,  is  not  the  cause  of  sending  away  the  money 
out  of  a  nation  ;  but  that  proceeds  from  the  difference  of  the  value  of  bullion  in 
every  country."  (N.  Barbon  ;  1.  c.  pp.  59,  60.)  MacCulloch  in  "the  Literature  of 
Political  Economy,  a  classified  catalogue,  Lond.  1845,"  praises  Barbon  for  this  anti- 
cipation, but  prudently  passes  over  the  naive  forms,  in  which  Barbon  clothes  the 
absurd  supposition  on  which  the  "currency  principle  "  is  based.  The  absence  of  real 
criticism  and  even  of  honesty,  in  that  catalogue,  culminates  in  the  sections  devoted 
to  the  history  of  the  theory  of  money ;  the  reason  is  that  MacCulloch  in  this  part  of 
the  work  is  flattering  Lord  Overstone  whom  he  calls  "facile  princeps  argentariorum." 

1  For  instance,  in  subsidies,  money  loans  for  carrying  on  wars  or  for  enabling  banks 
to  resume  cash  payments,  &c.,  it  is  the  money  form,  and  no  other,  of  value  that  may 
be  wanted. 


Money ^  or  the  Circulation  of  Commodities.    121 

the  markets  of  the  world.  The  functions  of  hoards,  therefore, 
arise  in  part  out  of  the  function  of  money,  as  the  medium  of 
the  home  circulation  and  home  payments,  and  in  part  out 
of  its  function  of  money  of  the  world.^  For  this  latter  func- 
tion, the  genuine  money-commodity,  actual  gold  and  silver,  is 
necessary.  On  that  account,  Sir  James  Steuart,  in  order  to 
distinguish  them  from  their  purely  local  substitutes,  calls  gold 
and  silver  "money  of  the  world." 

The  current  of  the  stream  of  gold  and  silver  is  a  double  one. 
On  the  one  hand,  it  spreads  itself  from  its  sources  over  all  the 
markets  of  the  world,  in  order  to  become  absorbed,  to  various 
extents,  into  the  different  national  spheres  of  circulation,  to 
till  the  conduits  of  currency,  to  replace  abraded  gold  and  silver 
coins,  to  supply  the  material  of  articles  of  luxury,  and  to 
petrify  into  hoards.^  This  first  current  is  started  by  the 
countries  that  exchange  their  labour,  realised  in  commodities, 
for  the  labour  embodied  in  the  precious  metals  by  gold  and 
silver-producing  countries.  On  the  other  hand,  there  is  a  con- 
tinual flowing  backwards  and  forwards  of  gold  and  silver  be- 
tween the  different  national  spheres  of  circulation,  a  current 
whose  motion  depends  on  the  ceaseless  fluctuations  in  the 
course  of  exchano^e.^ 

Countries  in  which  the  bourgeois  form  of  production  is  de- 
veloped to  a  certain  extent,  limit  the  hoards  concentrated  in 
the  strong  rooms  of  the  banks  to  the  minimum  required  for 


1  "  I  would  desire,  indeed,  no  more  convincing  evidence  of  the  competency  of  bhe 
machinery  of  the  hoards  in  specie-paying  countries  to  perform  every  necessary  oflSce 
of  international  adjustment,  without  any  sensible  aid  from  the  general  circulation, 
than  the  facility  with  which  France,  when  but  just  recovering  from  the  shock  of  a 
destructive  foreign  invasion,  completed  within  the  space  of  27  months  the  payment 
of  her  forced  contribution  of  nearly  20  millions  to  the  allied  powers,  and  a  consider- 
able proportion  of  the  sum  in  specie,  without  any  perceptible  contraction  or  derange- 
ment of  her  domestic  currency,  or  even  any  alarming  fluctuation  of  her  exchanges.'* 
(FuUarton,  1.  c,  p.  134.) 

2  "  L'argent  se  partage  entre  les  nations  relativement  au  besoin  qu'elles  en  ont .  .  . 
ctant  tou jours  attir6  par  les  productions."  (Le  Trosne  1.  c,  p.  916.)  "  The  mines 
which  are  continually  giving  gold  and  silver,  do  give  suflBcient  to  supply  such  a  need- 
ful balance  to  every  nation."    (J.  Yanderlint,  1.  c,  p.  40.) 

3  "  Exchanges  rise  and  fall  every  week,  and  at  some  particular  times  in  the  year 
run  high  against  a  nation,  and  at  other  times  run  as  high  on  the  contrary."  (N. 
Barbon,  1.  c.,p.  39.) 


122  Capitalist  Production. 

the  proper  performance  of  their  peculiar  functions.^  When- 
ever these  hoards  are  strikingly  above  their  average  level,  it 
is,  with  some  exceptions,  an  indication  of  stagnation  in  the 
circulation  of  commodities,  of  an  interruption  in  the  even  flow 
of  their  metamorphoses.^ 

1  These  various  functions  are  liable  to  come  into  flangerous  conflict  with  one  an- 
other whenever  gold  and  silver  have  also  to  serve  as  a  fund  for  the  conversion  of  bank- 
notes. 

2  "  What  money  is  more  than  of  absolute  necessity  for  a  Home  Trade,  is  dead 
stock  .  .  .  and  brings  no  profit  to  that  country  it's  kept  in,  but  as  it  is  transported  in 
trade,  as  well  as  imported."  (John  Bellers,  Essays,  p.  12.)  "What  if  we  have  too 
much  coin  ?  We  may  melt  down  the  heaviest  and  turn  it  into  the  splendour  of  plate, 
vessels  or  utensils  of  gold  or  silver  ;  or  send  it  out  as  a  commodity,  where  the  same 
is  wanted  or  desired  ;  or  let  it  out  at  interest,  where  interest  is  high. "  (W.  Petty : 
"  Quail tulumcunque,"  p.  39.)  "  Money  is  but  the  fat  of  the  Body  Politick,  whereof 
too  much  doth  as  often  hinder  its  agility,  as  too  little  makes  it  sick  ....  as  fat 
lubricates  the  motion  of  the  muscles,  feeds  in  want  of  victuals,  fills  up  the  uneven 
cavities,  and  beautifies  the  body ;  so  doth  money  in  the  state  quicken  its  action,  feeds 
from  abroad  in  time  of  dearth  at  home  ;  evens  accounts  .  .  and  beautifies  the  whole  ; 
altho  more  especially  the  particular  persons  that  have  it  in  plenty."  (W.  Petty, 
"  Political  Anatomy  of  Ireland,"  p.  14.) 


^ 


PART   II. 

THE  TRANSFORMATION   OF  MONEY   INTO 

CAPITAL. 


CHAPTER  IV. 

THE   GENERAL   FORMULA  FOR   CAPITAL. 

The  circulation  of  commodities  is  the  starting  point  of  capital. 
The  production  of  commodities,  their  circulation,  and  that  more 
developed  form  of  their  circulation  called  commerce,  these  form 
the  historical  groundwork  from  which  it  rises.  The  modern 
history  of  capital  dates  from  the  creation  in  the  16th  century 
of  a  world-embracing  commerce  and  a  world-embracing  market. 

If  we  abstract  from  the  material  substance  of  the  circulation 
of  commodities,  that  is,  from  the  exchange  of  the  various  use- 
values,  and  consider  only  the  economic  forms  produced  by  this 
process  of  circulation,  we  find  its  final  result  to  be  money  :  this 
final  product  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  is  the  first  form 
in  which  capital  appears. 

As  a  matter  of  history,  capital,  as  opposed  to  landed  property, 
invariably  takes  the  form  at  first  of  money;  it  appears  as 
moneyed  wealth,  as  the  capital  of  the  merchant  and  of  the 
usurer.^  But  we  have  no  need  to  refer  to  the  origin  of  capital 
in  order  to  discover  that  the  first  form  of  appearance  of  capital 
is  money.  We  can  see  it  daily  under  our  very  eyes.  All  new 
capital,  to  commence  with,  comes  on  the  stage,  that  is,  on  the 
market,  whether  of  commodities,  labour,  or  money,  even  in  our 

1  The  contrast  between  the  power,  based  on  the  personal  relations  of  dominion  and 
servitude,  that  is  conferred  by  landed  property,  and  the  impersonal  power  that  is 
given  by  money,  is  well  expressed  by  the  two  French  proverbs,  "  NuUe  terre  sans 
seigneur,"  and  "  L'argent  n'a  pas  de  maitre." 


124  Capitalist  Production. 

days,  in  the  shape  of  money  that  by  a  definite  process  has  to 
be  transformed  into  capital. 

The  first  distinction  we  notice  between  money  that  is  money 
only,  and  money  that  is  capital,  is  nothing  more  than  a  diflfer- 
ence  in  their  form  of  circulation. 

The  simplest  form  of  the  circulation  of  commodities  is  C — 
M — C,  the  transformation  of  commodities  into  money,  and  the 
change  of  the  money  back  again  into  commodities ;  or  selling  in 
order  to  buy.  But  alongside  of  this  form  we  find  another 
specifically  diflferent  form:  M — C — M,  the  transformation  of 
money  into  commodities,  and  the  change  of  commodities  back 
again  into  money ;  or  buying  in  order  to  sell.  Money  that 
circulates  in  the  latter  manner  is  thereby  transformed  into,  be- 
comes capital,  and  is  already  potentially  capital. 

Now  let  us  examine  the  circuit  M — C — M  a  little  closer.  It 
consists,  like  the  other,  of  two  antithetical  phases.  In  the  first 
phase,  M — C,  or  the  purchase,  the  money  is  changed  into  a  com- 
modity. In  the  second  phase,  C — M,  or  the  sale,  the  commodity 
is  changed  back  again  into  money.  The  combination  of  these 
two  phases  constitutes  the  single  movement  whereby  money  is 
exchanged  for  a  commodity,  and  the  same  commodity  is  again 
exchanged  for  money;  whereby  a  commodity  is  bought  in  order 
to  be  sold,  or,  neglecting  the  distinction  in  form  between  buying 
and  selling,  whereby  a  commodity  is  bought  with  money,  and 
then  money  is  bought  with  a  commodit}^^  The  result,  in  which 
the  phases  of  the  process  vanish,  is  the  exchange  of  money  for 
money,  M— M.  If  I  purchase  2000  lbs.  of  cotton  for  £100,  and 
resell  the  2000  lbs.  of  cotton  for  £110, 1  have,  in  fact,  exchanged 
£100  for  £110,  money  for  money. 

Now  it  is  evident  that  the  circuit  M — C — M  would  be 
absurd  and  without  meaning  if  the  intention  were  to  exchange 
by  this  means  two  equal  sums  of  money,  £100  for  £100.  The 
miser's  plan  would  be  far  simpler  and  surer ;  he  sticks  to  his 
£100  instead  of  exposing  it  to  the  dangers  of  circulation.  And 
yet,  whether  the  merchant  who  has  paid  £100  for  his  cotton 

1  "Avec  de  I'argent  on  achete  des  marchandises,  et  avec  des  marchandises  on 
acliete  de  I'argent."  (Mercier  de  la  Eiviere  :  *'  L'ordre  natural  et  essentiel  des  societ^s 
politiques,"  j),  543.) 


The  General  Foi'imda  for  Capital.  125 

sells  it  for  £110,  or  lets  it  go  for  £100,  or  even  £50,  his  money 
has,  at  all  events,  gone  through  a  characteristic  and  original 
movement,  quite  different  in  kind  from  that  which  it  goes 
through  in  the  hands  of  the  peasant  who  sells  corn,  and  with 
the  money  thus  set  free  buys  clothes.  We  have  therefore  to 
examine  first  the  distinguishing  characteristics  of  the  forms  of 
the  circuits  M — C — M  and  C — M — C,  and  in  doing  this  the 
real  difference  that  underlies  the  mere  difference  of  form  will 
reveal  itself. 

Let  us  see,  in  the  first  place,  what  the  two  forms  have  in 
common. 

Both  circuits  are  resolvable  into  the  same  two  antithetical 
phases,  C — M,  a  sale,  and  M — C,  a  purchase.  In  each  of  these 
phases  the  same  material  elements — a  commodity,  and  money, 
and  the  same  economical  dramatis  personse,  a  buyer  and  a 
seller — confront  one  another.  Each  circuit  is  the  unity  of  the 
same  two  antithetical  phases,  and  in  each  case  this  unity  is 
brought  about  by  the  intervention  of  three  contracting  parties, 
of  whom  one  only  sells,  another  only  buys,  while  the  third  both 
buys  and  sells. 

What,  however,  first  and  foremost  distinguishes  the  circuit 
C — M — C  from  the  circuit  M — C — M,  is  the  inverted  order  of 
succession  of  the  two  phases.  The  simple  circulation  of  com- 
modities begins  with  a  sale  and  ends  with  a  purchase,  while 
the  circulation  of  money  as  capital  begins  with  a  purchase 
and  ends  with  a  sale.  In  the  one  case  both  the  starting- 
point  and  the  goal  are  commodities,  in  the  other  they  are 
money.  In  the  first  form  the  movement  is  brought  about 
by  the  intervention  of  money,  in  the  second  by  that  of  a 
commodity. 

In  the  circulation  C — M — C,  the  money  is  in  the  end  con- 
verted into  a  commodity,  that  serves  as  a  use- value ;  it  is  spent 
once  for  all.  In  the  inverted  form,  M — C — M,  on  the  contrary, 
the  buyer  lays  out  money  in  order  that,  as  a  seller,  he 
may  recover  money.  By  the  purchase  of  his  commodity 
he  throws  money  into  circulation,  in  order  to  withdraw 
it  again  by  the  sale  of  the  same  commodity.  He  lets  the 
money  go,   but    only  with    the   sly  intention    of  getting   it 


126  Capitalist  Production. 

back  again.     The  money,  therefore,  is  not  spent,  it  is  merely 
advanced/ 

In  the  circuit  C — M — C,  the  same  piece  of  money  changes 
its  place  twice.  The  seller  gets  it  from  the  buyer  and  pays  it 
away  to  another  seller.  The  complete  circulation,  which  begins 
with  the  receipt,  concludes  with  the  payment,  of  money  for 
commodities.  It  is  the  very  contrary  in  the  circuit  M — C — M. 
Here  it  is  not  the  piece  of  money  that  changes  its  place  twice, 
but  the  commodity.  The  buyer  takes  it  from  the  hands  of 
the  seller  and  passes  it  into  the  hands  of  another  buyer.  Just 
as  in  the  simple  circulation  of  commodities  the  double  change 
of  place  of  the  same  piece  of  money  effects  its  passage  from  one 
hand  into  another,  so  here  the  double  change  of  place  of  the 
same  commodity  brings  about  the  reflux  of  the  money  to  its 
point  of  departure. 

Such  reflux  is  not  dependent  on  the  commodity  being  sold 
for  more  than  was  paid  for  it.  This  circumstance  influences 
only  the  amount  of  the  money  that  comes  back. .  The  reflux 
itself  takes  place,  so  soon  as  the  purchased  commodity  is  re- 
sold, in  other  words,  so  soon  as  the  circuit  M — C — M  is  com- 
pleted. We  have  here,  therefore,  a  palpable  difference  between 
the  circulation  of  money  as  capital,  and  its  circulation  as  mere 
money. 

The  circuit  C — M — C  comes  completely  to  an  end,  so  soon 
as  the  money  bi ought  in  by  the  sale  of  one  commodity  is 
abstracted  again  by  the  purchase  of  another. 

If,  nevertheless,  there  follows  a  reflux  of  money  to  its  start- 
ing point,  this  can  only  happen  through  a  renewal  or  repeti- 
tion of  the  operation.  If  I  sell  a  quarter  of  corn  for  £3,  and 
with  this  £3  buy  clothes,  the  money,  so  far  as  I  am  concerned, 
is  spent  and  done  with.  It  belongs  to  the  clothes  merchant. 
If  I  now  sell  a  second  quarter  of  corn,  money  indeed  flows 
back  to  me,  not  however  as  a  sequel  to  the  first  transaction, 
but  in  consequence  of  its  repetition.  The  money  again  leaves 
me,  so  soon  as  I  complete  this  second  transaction  by  a  fresh 

1  ' '  When  a  thing  is  bought  in  order  to  be  sold  again,  the  sum  employed  is  called 
money  advanced  ;  when  it  is  bought  not  to  be  sold,  it  may  be  said  to  be  expended." — 
(James  Steuart :  "  AVorks,"  &c.  Edited  by  Gen.  Sir  James  Steuart,  his  son.  Lond., 
1805.    V.  I.,  p.  274.) 


The  General  Formula  for  Capital,  127 

purchase.  Therefore,  in  the  circuit  C — M — C,  the  expenditure 
of  money  has  nothing  to  do  with  its  reflux.  On  the  other 
hand,  in  M — C — M,  the  reflux  of  the  money  is  conditioned  by 
the  very  mode  of  its  expenditure.  Without  this  reflux,  the 
operation  fails,  or  the  process  is  interrupted  and  incomplete, 
owing  to  the  absence  of  its  complementary  and  final  phase,  the 
sale. 

The  circuit  C — M — C  starts  with  one  commodity,  and 
finishes  with  another,  which  falls  out  of  circulation  and  into 
consumption.  Consumption,  the  satisfaction  of  wants,  in  one 
word,  use-value,  is  its  end  and  aim.  The  circuit  M — C — M, 
on  the  contrary,  commences  with  money  and  ends  with  money. 
Its  leading  motive,  and  the  goal  that  attracts  it,  is  therefore 
mere  exchange  value. 

In  the  simple  circulation  of  commodities,  the  two  extremes  of 
the  circuit  have  the  same  economic  form.  They  are  both  com- 
modities, and  commodities  of  equal  value.  But  they  are  also 
use- values  differing  in  their  qualities,  as,  for  example,  corn  and 
clothes.  The  exchange  of  products,  of  the  different  materials  in 
which  the  labour  of  society  is  embodied,  forms  here  the  basis 
of  the  movement.  It  is  otherwise  in  the  circulation  M — C — M, 
which  at  first  sight  appears  purposeless,  because  tautological. 
Both  extremes  have  the  same  economic  form.  They  are  both 
money,  and  therefore  are  not  qualitatively  different  use-values  ; 
for  money  is  but  the  converted  form  of  commodities,  in  which 
their  particular  use-values  vanish.  To  exchange  £100  for 
cotton,  and  then  this  same  cotton  again  for  £100,  is  merely  a 
roundabout  way  of  exchanging  money  for  money,  the  same  for 
the  same,  and  appears  to  be  an  operation  just  as  purposeless  as 
it  is  absurd.^   One  sum  of  money  is  distinguishable  from  another 

1  **0n  n'echange  pas  de  Vargent  centre  de  I'argent,"  says  Mercier  de  la  Riviere  to 
the  Mercantilists  (1.  c,  p.  486.)  In  a  work,  which,  ex  professo,  treats  of  "  trade  "  and 
"speculation,'-  occurs  the  following  :  "  All  trade  consists  in  the  exchange  of  things 
of  different  kinds;  and  the  advantage"  (to  the  merchant?)  "arises  out  of  this 
difference.  To  exchange  a  pound  of  bread  against  a  pound  of  bread  .... 
would  be  attended  with  no  advantage ;  .  .  .  .  Hence  trade  is  advantageously- 
contrasted  with  gambling,  which  consists  in  a  mere  exchange  of  money  for  money." 
(Th.  Corbet,  "  An  Inquiry  into  the  Causes  and  Modes  of  the  Wealth  of  Individuals  ; 
or  the  Principles  of  Trade  and  Speculation  explained."  London,  1841,  p.  5.)  Although 
Corbet  does  not  see  that  M — M,  the  exchange  of  money  for  money,  is  the  characteristic 


',..^ 


128  Capitalist  Production, 

only  by  its  amount.  The  character  and  tendency  of  the  pro- 
cess M — C — M,  is  therefore  not  due  to  any  qualitative  difference 
between  its  extremes,  both  being  money,  but  solely  to  their 
quantitative  difference.  More  money  is  withdrawn  from  circula- 
tion at  the  finish  than  was  thrown  into  it  at  the  start.  The 
cotton  that  was  bought  for  £100  is  perhaps  resold  for  £100  + 
£10  or  £110.  The  exact  form  of  this  process  is  therefore  M — 
G — M',  where  M'  =  M  +  A  M  =  the  original  sum  advanced, 
plus  an  increment.  This  increment  or  excess  over  the  original 
value  I  call  "  surplus-value."  The  value  originally  advanced, 
therefore,  not  only  remains  intact  while  in  circulation,  but  adds 
to  itself  a  surplus-value  or  expands  itself  It  is  this  movement 
that  converts  it  into  capital. 

Of  course,  it  is  also  possible,  that  in  C — M — C,  the  two 
extremes  C — C,  say  corn  and  clothes,  may  represent  different 
quantities  of  value.  The  farmer  may  sell  his  corn  above  its 
value,  or  may  buy  the  clothes  at  less  than  their  value.  He 
may,  on  the  other  hand,  "  be  done  "  by  the  clothes  merchant. 
Yet,  in  the  form  of  circulation  now  under  consideration,  such 
differences  in  value  are  purely  accidental.  The  fact  that  the 
corn  and  the  clothes  are  equivalents,  does  not  deprive  the  pro- 
cess of  all  meaning,  as  it  does  in  M — C — M.  The  equivalence 
of  their  values  is  rather  a  necessary  condition  to  its  normal 
course. 

The  repetition  or  renewal  of  the  act  of  selling  in  order  to 
buy,  is  kept  within  bounds  by  the  very  object  it  aims  at, 
namely,  consumption  or  the  satisfaction  of  definite  wants,  an 
aim  that  lies  altogether  outside  the  sphere  of  circulation.  But 
when  we  buy  in  order  to  sell,  we,  on  the  contrary,  begin  and 

form  of  circulation,  not  only  of  merchants'  capital  but  of  all  capital,  yet  at  least  he 
acknowledges  that  this  form  is  common  to  gambling  and  to  one  species  of  trade,  viz., 
speculation  :  but  then  comes  MacCulloch  and  makes  out,  that  to  buy  in  order  to  sell, 
is  to  speculate,  and  thus  the  difference  between  Speculation  and  Trade  vanishes. 
"Every  transaction  in  which  an  individual  buys  produce  in  order  to  sell  it  again,  is, 
in  fact,  a  speculation."  (MacCulloch  :  "  A  Dictionary  Practical,  &c.,  of  Commerce." 
Lond.,  1847,  p.  1058.)  With  much  more  naivete,  Pinto,  the  Pindar  of  the  Amster- 
dam Stock  Exchange,  remarks,  "  Le  commerce  est  un  jeu  :  (taken  from  Locke)  et  ce 
u'est  pas  avec  des  gueux  qu'on  peut  gagner.  Si  Ton  gagnait  long-temps  en  tout  avec 
fcous,  il  faudrait  rendre  de  bon  accord  les  plus  grandes  i)arties  du  profit  pour  recom- 
mencer  le  jeu."  (Pinto :  "  Traite  de  la  Circulation  et  du  Credit."  Amsterdam,  1771, 
p.  231.) 


The  General  For mtda  for  Capital,  129 

end  with  the  same  thing,  money,  exchange- value ;  and  thereby 
the  movement  becomes  interminable.  No  doubt,  M  becomes 
M  -f  ^  M,  £100  become  £110.  But  when  viewed  in  their 
qualitative  aspect  alone,  £110  are  the  same  as  £100,  namely 
money;  and  considered  quantitatively,  £110  is,  like  £100,  a 
sum  of  definite  and  limited  value.  If  now,  the  £110  be  spent 
as  money,  they  cease  to  play  their  part.  They  are  no  longer 
capital.  Withdrawn  from  circulation,  they  become  petrified 
into  a  hoard,  and  though  they  remained  in  that  state  till 
doomsday,  not  a  single  farthing  would  accrue  to  them.  If, 
then,  the  expansion  of  value  is  once  aimed  at,  there  is  just  the 
same  inducement  to  augment  the  value  of  the  £110  as  that  of 
the  £100  ;  for  both  are  but  limited  expressions  for  exchange- 
value,  and  therefore  both  have  the  same  vocation  to  approach, 
by  quantitative  increase,  as  near  as  possible  to  absolute  wealth. 
Momentarily,  indeed,  the  value  originally  advanced,  the  £100 
is  distinguishable  from  the  surplus  value  of  £10  that  is  an- 
nexed to  it  during  circulation;  but  the  distinction  vanishes 
immediately.  At  the  end  of  the  process,  we  do  not  receive 
with  one  hand  the  original  £100,  and  with  the  other,  the 
surplus- value  of  £10.  We  simply  get  a  value  of  £110,  which 
is  in  exactly  the  same  condition  and  fitness  for  commencing 
the  expanding  process,  as  the  original  £100  was.  Money  ends 
the  movement  only  to  begin  it  again.^  Therefore,  the  final 
result  of  every  separate  circuit,  in  which  a  purchase  and  con- 
sequent sale  are  completed,  forms  of  itself  the  starting  point 
of  a  new  circuit.  The  simple  circulation  of  commodities — 
selling  in  order  to  buy — is  a  means  of  carrying  out  a  purpose 
unconnected  with  circulation,  namely,  the  appropriation  of 
use-values,  the  satisfaction  of  wants.  The  circulation  of  money 
as  capital  is,  on  the  contrary,  an  end  in  itself,  for  the  expansion 
of  value  takes  place  only  within  this  constantly  renewed 
movement.     The  circulation  of  capital  has  therefore  no  limits.^ 

1  "  Capital  is  divisible  ....  into  the  original  capital  and  the  profit,  the  increment 
to  the  capital  ....  although  in  j)ractice  this  profit  is  immediately  turned  into 
capital,  and  set  in  motion  with  the  original."  (F.  Engels,  "Umrisse  zu  einer  Kritik 
der  Nationalokonomie,  in :  Deutsch-Franzosische  Juhrbiicher,  herausgegeben  von 
Arnold  Ruge  und  Karl  Marx."    Paris,  1844,  p.  99.) 

2  Aristotle  opposes  CEconomic  to  Chrematistic.  He  starts  from  the  former.  So 
far  as  it  is  the  art  of  gaining  a  livelihood,  it  is  limited  to  procuring  those  articles. 


130  Capitalist  Production. 

As  the  conscious  representative  of  this  movement,  the 
possessor  of  money  becomes  a  capitalist.  His  person,  or  rather 
his  pocket,  is  the  point  from  which  the  money  starts  and  to 
which  it  returns.  The  expansion  of  value,  which  is  the 
objective  basis  or  main-spring  of  the  circulation  M — C — M, 
becomes  his  subjective  aim,  and  it  is  only  in  so  far  as  the 
appropriation  of  ever  more  and  more  wealth  in  the  abstract 
becomes  the  sole  motive  of  his  operations,  that  he  functions  as 
a  capitalist,  that  is,  as  capital  personified  and  endowed  with 
consciousness  and  a  will.  Use-values  must  therefore  never 
be  looked  upon  as  the  real  aim  of  the  capitalist;^  neither 
must  the  profit  on  any  single  transaction.  The  restless  never- 
ending  process  of  profit-making  alone  is  what  he  aims  at.^ 

that  are  necessary  to  existence,  and  useful  either  to  a  household  or  the  sta,te.  *'  True 
wealth  (0  dXn^ivos  ^kovroi)  consists  of  such  values  in  use  ;  for  the  quantity  of  pos- 
sessions  of  this  kind,  capable  of  making  life  pleasant,  is  not  unlimited.  There  is, 
however,  a  second  mode  of  acquiring  things,  to  which  we  may  by  preference  and 
with  correctness  give  the  name  of  Chrematistic,  and  in  this  case  there  appear  to  be 
no  limits  to  riches  and  possessions.  Trade  {h  xacr»jX/x«  is  literally  retail  trade,  and 
Aristotle  takes  this  kind  because  in  it  values  in  use  predominate)  does  not  in  its 
natm-e  belong  to  Chrematistic,  for  here  the  exchange  has  reference  only  to  what  is 
necessary  to  themselves  (the  buyer  or  seller)."  Therefore,  as  he  goes  on  to  show, 
the  original  form  of  trade  was  barter,  but  with  the  extension  of  the  latter,  there 
arose  the  necessity  for  money.  On  the  discovery  of  money,  barter  of  necessity  de- 
veloped into  xwrnXixhf  into  trading  in  commodities,  and  this  again,  in  opposition  to 
its  original  tendency,  grew  into  Chrematistic,  into  the  art  of  making  money.  Now 
Chrematistic  is  distinguishable  from  (Economic  in  this  way,  that  "  in  the  case  of 
Chrematistic,  circulation  is  the  source  of  riches  {-roLtiTixh  ;^prif/.ciTa>v  .  .  .  .  'hia 
XpvfcdTcuv  ltaP>o\ris).  And  it  appears  to  revolve  about  money,  for  money  is  the  be- 
ginning and  end  of  this  kind  of  exchange  (to  yap  vofjuffjia  o-roix'-'tov  xai  -r'tpai  rrj: 
tkWayTJs  IffTiv).  Therefore  also  riches,  such  as  Chrematistic  strives  for,  are  un- 
limited. Just  as  every  art  that  is  not  a  means  to  an  end,  but  an  end  in  itself,  has 
no  limit  to  its  aims,  because  it  seeks  constantly  to  approach  nearer  and  nearer  to 
that  end,  while  those  arts  that  pursue  means  to  an  end,  are  not  boundless,  since 
the  goal  itself  imposes  a  limit  upon  them,  so  with  Chrematistic,  there  are  no  bounds 
to  its  aims,  these  aims  being  absolute  wealth.  (Economic  not  Chrematistic  has  a 
limit  ....  the  object  of  the  former  is  something  different  from  money,  of  the 
latter  the  augmentation  of  money  ....  By  confounding  these  two  forms,  which 
overlap  each  other,  some  people  have  been  led  to  look  upon  the  preservation  and 
increase  of  money  ad  infinitum  as  the  end  and  aim  of  (Economic. "  (Aristoteles  De 
Rep.  edit.  Bekker.  lib.  I.  c.  8,  9.  passim.) 

1  "Commodities  (here  used  in  the  sense  of  use-values)  are  not  the  terminating  object 
of  the  trading  capitalist,  money  is  his  terminating  object."  (Th.  Chalmers,  On  Pol, 
Econ.  &c.,  2nd  Ed.,  Glasgow,  1832,  p.  165,  16G.) 

"II  mercante  non  conta  quasi  per  niente  il  lucro  fatto,  ma  mira  sempre  al  futuro.' 
(A.  Genovesi,  Lezioni  di  Economia  Civile  (1765),  Custodi's  edit,  of  Italian  Economists. 
Parte  Moderna  t.  viii.  p.  139.) 


The  Geiteral  FormiUa  for  Capital,  1 3 1 

This  boundless  greed  after  riches,  this  passionate  chase  after 
exchange- value,!  is  common  to  the  capitalist  and  the  miser ; 
but  while  the  miser  is  merely  a  capitalist  gone  mad,  the 
capitalist  is  a  rational  miser.  The  never-ending  augmentation 
of  exchange-value,  which  the  miser  strives  after,  by  seeking  to 
save^  his  money  from  circulation,  is  attained  by  the  more  acute 
capitalist,  by  constantly  throwing  it  afresh  into  circulation.^ 

The  independent  form,  i.e.y  the  money-form,  which  the  value 
of  commodities  assumes  in  the  case  of  simple  circulation,  serves 
only  one  purpose,  namely,  their  exchange,  and  vanishes  in  the 
final  result  of  the  movement.  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  circula- 
tion M — C — M,  both  the  money  and  the  commodity  represent 
only  different  modes  of  existence  of  value  itself,  the  money  its 
general  mode,  and  the  commodity  its  particular,  or,  so  to  say, 
disguised  mode.^  It  is  constantly  changing  from  one  form  to 
the  other  without  thereby  becoming  lost,  and  thus  assumes  an 
automatically  active  character.  If  now  we  take  in  turn  each 
of  the  two  different  forms  which  self-expanding  value  suc- 
cessively assumes  in  the  course  of  its  life,  we  then  arrive  at 
these  two  propositions :  Capital  is  money :  Capital  is  com- 
modities.'^  In  truth,  however,  value  is  here  the  active  factor  in 
a  process,  in  which,  while  constantly  assuming  the  form  in  turn 
of  money  and  commodities,  it  at  the  same  time  changes  in 
magnitude,  differentiates  itself  by  throwing  off  surplus- value 
from  itself;  the  original  value,  in  other  words,  expands  spon- 
taneously. For  the  movement,  in  the  course  of  which  it  adds 
surplus  value,  is  its  own  movement,  its  expansion,  therefore,  is 

1  "  The  inextinguishable  passion  for  gain,  the  auri  sacra  fames,  will  always  lead 
capitalists."  (MacCuUoch:  "  The  principles  of  Polit.  Econ."  London,  1830,  p.  179.)  This 
view,  of  course,  does  not  prevent  the  same  MacCulloch  and  others  of  his  kidney, 
when  in  theoretical  difficulties,  such,  for  example,  as  the  question  of  over-production, 
from  transforming  the  same  capitalist  into  a  moral  citizen,  whose  sole  concern  is  for 
use-values,  and  who  even  developes  an  insatiable  hunger  for  boots,  hats,  eggs,  calico, 
and  other  extremely  familiar  sorts  of  use-values. 

2  ^oZ,iiv  is  a  characteristic  Greek  expression  for  hoarding.  So  in  English  to  save 
has  the  same  two  meanings  :  sauver  and  epargner. 

3  "  Questo  infinito  che  le  cose  non  hanno  in  progresso,  hanno  in  giro."  (Galiani.) 

4  *'  Ce  n'est  pas  la  matiere  qui  fait  le  capital,  mais  la  valgur  de  ces  matieres."  (J. 
B.  Say  :  "Traite  de  I'Econ.  Polit."  3  erne.  ed.     Paris,  1817,  t.  1.,  p.  428.) 

5  "  Currency  (!)  employed  in  iDroducing  articles  ...  is  capital."  (MacLeod  :  "The 
Theory  and  Practice  of  Banking. "  London,  1855,  v.  1. ,  ch.  i. ,  p.  55. )  "  Capital  is  com- 
modities."   (James  Mill :  "  Elements  of  Pol.  Econ."    Lond.,  1821,  p.  74.) 


132  Capitalist  ProdtLctioii. 

automatic  expansion.  Because  it  is  value,  it  has  acquired  the 
occult  quality  of  being  able  to  add  value  to  itself.  It  brings 
forth  living  offspring,  or,  at  the  least,  lays  golden  eggs. 

Value,  therefore,  being  the  active  factor  in  such  a  process, 
and  assuming  at  one  time  the  form  of  money,  at  another  that 
of  commodities,  but  through  all  these  changes  preserving  itself 
and  expanding,  it  requires  some  independent  form,  by  means  of 
which  its  identity  may  at  any  time  be  established.  And  this 
form  it  possesses  only  in  the  shape  of  money.  It  is  under  the 
form  of  money  that  value  begins  and  ends,  and  begins  again, 
every  act  of  its  own  spontaneous  generation.  It  began  by 
being  £100,  it  is  now  £110,  and  so  on.  But  the  money  itself 
is  only  one  of  the  two  forms  of  value.  Unless  it  takes  the  form 
of  some  commodity,  it  does  not  become  capital.  There  is  here 
no  antagonism,  as  in  the  case  of  hoarding,  between  the  mone}^ 
and  commodities.  The  capitalist  knows  that  all  commodities, 
however  scurvy  they  may  look,  or  however  badly  they  may 
smell,  are  in  faith  and  in  truth  money,  inwardly  circumcised 
Jews,  and  what  is  more,  a  wonderful  means  whereby  out  of 
money  to  make  more  money. 

In  simple  circulation,  C — M — C,  the  value  of  commodities 
attained  at  the  most  a  form  independent  of  their  use-values,  i.e., 
the  form  of  money ;  but  that  same  value  now  in  the  circulation 
M — C — M,  or  the  circulation  of  capital,  suddenly  presents  itself 
as  an  independent  substance,  endowed  with  a  motion  of  its  own, 
passing  through  a  life- process  of  its  own,  in  which  money  and 
commodities  are  mere  forms  which  it  assumes  and  casts  off  in 
turn.  Nay,  more :  instead  of  simply  representing  the  relations 
of  commodities,  it  enters  now,  so  to  say,  into  private  relations 
with  itself.  It  differentiates  itself  as  original  value  from  itself 
as  surplus- value;  as  the  father  differentiates  himself  from  himself 
qua  the  son,  yet  both  are  one  and  of  one  age:  for  only  by  the  surplus 
value  of  £10  does  the  £100  originally  advanced  become  capital, 
and  so  soon  as  this  takes  place,  so  soon  as  the  son,  and  by  the 
son,  the  father,  is  begotten,  so  soon  does  their  difference  vanish, 
and  they  again  become  one,  £110. 

Value  therefore  now  becomes  value  in  process,  money  in  pro- 
cess, and,  as  such,  capital.     It  comes  out  of  circulation,  enters 


Contradictions  in  the  Formula  of  Capital,      133 

into  it  again,  preserves  and  multiplies  itself  within  its  circuit, 
comes  back  out  of  it  with  expanded  bulk,  and  begins  the  same 
round  ever  afresh.^  M — M',  money  which  begets  money, 
such  is  the  description  of  Capital  from  the  mouths  of  its  first 
interpreters,  the  Mercantilists. 

Buying  in  order  to  sell,  or,  more  accurately,  buying  in  order 
to  sell  dearer,  M — C — M',  appears  certainly  to  be  a  form 
peculiar  to  one  kind  of  capital  alone,  namely,  merchants'  capital. 
But  industrial  capital  too  is  money,  that  is  changed  into  com- 
modities, and  by  the  sale  of  these  commodities,  is  re-converted 
into  more  money.  The  events  that  take  place  outside  the 
sphere  of  circulation,  in  the  interval  between  the  buying  and 
selling,  do  not  affect  the  form  of  this  movement.  Lastly,  in  the 
case  of  interest-bearing  capital,  the  circulation  M — C — M' 
appears  abridged.  We  have  its  result  without  the  intermediate 
stage,  in  the  form  M — M',  "  en  style  lapidaire  "  so  to  say,  money 
that  is  worth  more  money,  value  that  is  greater  than  itself. 

M — C — M'  is  therefore  in  reality  the  general  formula  of 
capital  as  it  appears  prima  facie  within  the  sphere  of  circulation. 


CHAPTER  V. 

CONTRADICTIONS  IN   THE   GENERAL   FORMULA  OF  CAPITAL. 

The  form  which  circulation  takes  when  money  becomes 
capital,  is  opposed  to  all  the  laws  we  have  hitherto  investigated 
bearing  on  the  nature  of  commodities,  value  and  money,  and 
even  of  circulation  itself.  What  distinguishes  this  form  from 
that  of  the  simple  circulation  of  commodities,  is  the  inverted 
order  of  succession  of  the  two  antithetical  processes,  sale  and 
purchase.  How  can  this  purely  formal  distinction  between 
these  processes  change  their  character  as  it  were  by  magic  ? 

But  that  is  not  all.  This  inversion  has  no  existence  for  two 
out  of  the  three  persons  who  transact  business  together.  As 
capitalist,  I  buy  commodities  from  A  and  sell  them  again  to  B, 

1  Capital :  "  portion  fructifiante  de  la  richesse  accumulee  .  .  .  valeur  permanente, 
multipliante."    (Sismondi :  "Nouveaux  principes  de  I'econ,  polit.,"  t.  1.,  p.  88,  89.) 


134  Capitalist  Production. 

but  as  a  simple  owner  of  commodities,  I  sell  them  to  B  and  then 
purchase  fresh  ones  from  A.  A  and  B  see  no  difference 
between  the  two  sets  of  transactions.  They  are  merely  buyers 
or  sellers.  And  I  on  each  occasion  meet  them  as  a  mere  owner 
of  either  money  or  commodities,  as  a  buyer  or  a  seller,  and, 
what  is  more,  in  both  sets  of  transactions,  I  am  opposed  to  A 
only  as  a  buyer  and  to  B  only  as  a  seller,  to  the  one  only  as 

(money,  to  the  other  only  as  commodities,  and  to  neither  of  I 
them  as  capital  or  a  capitalist,  or  as  representative  of  anything   I 
that  is  more  than  money  or  commodities,  or  that  can  produce  | 
any  effect  beyond  what  money  and  commodities  can.     For  me 
the  purchase  from  A  and  the  sale  to  B  are  part  of  a  series. 
But  the  connexion  between  the  two  acts  exists  for  me  alone. 
A  does  not  trouble  himself  about  my  transaction  with  B,  nor 
does  B  about  my  business  with  A.     And  if  I  offered  to  explain 
to  them  the  meritorious  nature  of  my  action  in  inverting  the 
order  of  succession,  they  would  probably  point  out  to  me  that 
I  was  mistaken  as  to  that  order  of  succession,  and  that  the 
whole  transaction,  instead  of  beginning  with  a  purchase  and 
ending  with  a  sale,  began,  on  the  contrary,  with  a  sale  and  was 
concluded  with  a  purchase.     In  truth,  my  first  act,  the  purchase, 
was  from  the  standpoint  of  A,  a  sale,  and  my  second  act,  the 
sale,  was  from  the  standpoint  of  B,  a  purchase.     Not  content  f 
with  that,  A  and  B  would  declare  that  the  whole  series  was  I 
superfluous  and  nothing  but  Hokus  Pokus ;  that  for  the  future  ( 
A  would  buy  direct  from  B,  and  B  sell  direct  to  A.     Thus  the 
whole  transaction  would  be  reduced  to  a  single  act  forming  an 
isolated,  non-complemented  phase  in  the  ordinary  circulation 
of  commodities,  a  mere  sale  from  A's  point  of  view,  and  from 
B's,  a  mere  purchase.     The  inversion,  therefore,  of  the  order  of 
succession,  does  not  take  us  outside  the  sphere  of  the  simple 
circulation  of  commodities,  and  we  must  rather  look,  whether 
there  is  in  this  simple  circulation  anything  permitting  an  ex- 
pansion '  of  the  value  that  enters  into  circulation,  and,  con- 
sequently, a  creation  of  surplus- value. 

Let  us  take  the  process  of  circulation  in  a  form  under  which 
it  presents  itself  as  a  simple  and  direct  exchange  of  commodities. 
This  is  always  the  case  when  two  owners  of  commodities  buy 


Contradictions  in  the  Formida  of  Capital.     135 

from  each  other,  and  on  the  settling  day  the  amounts  mutually 
owing  are  equal  and  cancel  each  other.     The  money  in  this 
case  is  money  of  account  and  serves  to  express  the  value  of  the 
commodities  by  their  prices,  but  is  not,  itself,  in  the  shape  of 
hard  cash,  confronted  with  them.     So  far  as  regards  use-values, 
it  is  clear  that  both  parties  may  gain  some  advantage.     Both 
part  with  goods  that,  as  use-values,  are  of  no  service  to  them, 
and  receive  others  that  they  can  make  use  of.     And  there  may 
also  be  a  further  gain.     A,  who  sells  wine   and  buys   corn, 
possibly  produces  more  wine,  with   given  labour   time,  than         \^ 
farmer  B  could,  and  B,  on  the  other  hand,  more  corn  than       .^J 
wine-grower  A  could.     A,  therefore,  may  get,   for  the  same  x       ^ 
exchange  value,  more  corn,  and  B  more  wine,  than  each  w^ould    ^v^ 
respectively  get  without  any  exchange  by  producing  his  own  ' 
corn  and  wine.     With  reference,  therefore,  to  use- value,  there 
is  good  ground  for  saying  that  "  exchange  is  a  transaction  by  ]     ^  ^ 
which  both  sides  gain."  ^     It  is  otherwise  with  exchange-value.      ^^Vi 
"  A  man  who  has  plenty  of  wine  and  no  corn  treats  with  a  man 
who  has  plenty  of  corn  and  no  wine  ;  an  exchange  takes  place 
between  them  of  com  to  the  value  of  50,  for  wine  of  the  same 
value.     This  act  produces  no  increase  of  exchange-value  either 
for  the  one  or  the  other ;  for  each  of  them  already  possessed, 
before  the  exchange,  a  value  equal  to  that  which  he  acquired 
by  means  of  that  operation."  ^     The  result  is  not  altered  by 
introducing  money,  as  a  medium  of  circulation,  between  the 
commodities,  and  making  the  sale  and  the  purchase  two  distinct 
acts.^     The  value  of  a  commodity  is  expressed  in  its  price 
before  it  goes  into  circulation,  and  is  therefore  a  precedent 
condition  of  circulation,  not  its  result.* 

Abstractedly  considered,  that  is,  apart  from  circu instances 
not  immediately  flowing  from  the  laws  of  the  simple  circulation 
of  commodities,  there  is  in  an  exchange  nothing  (if  we  except 

"i  "L'echange  est  une  transaction  admirable  dans  laquelle  les  deux  contractants 
gagnent — toujours  (!)  "  (Destutt  de  Tracy  :  "Traite  de  la  Volonte  et  de  ses  effets." 
Paris,  182G,  p.  68.)     This  work  appeared  afterwards  as  "  Traite  de  I'Econ.  Polit." 

2  "  Mercier  de  la  Eiviere,"  1.  c.  p.  544. 

s  "  Que  I'une  de  ces  deux  valeurs  soit  argent,  ou  qu'elles  soient  toutes  deux  mar. 
cbandises  usuelles,  rien  de  plus  indifferent  en  soi."  ("Mercier  de  la  Eiviere,"  1.  c.  p.  543. ) 

4  "  Ce  ne  sont  pas  les  contractants  qui  prononcent  sur  la  valeur  ;  elle  est  decidee 
avant  la  convention."    ("  Le  Trosne,"  p.  906.) 


N 


V 


Capitalist  Pi'od action, 

the  replacing  of  one  use-value  by  another)  but  a  metamorphosis, 
NJa  mere  change  in  the  form  of  the  commodity.  The  same 
;  exchange  value,  i.e.,  the  same  quantity  of  incorporated  social 
labour,  remains  throughout  in  the  hands  of  the  owner  of  the 
commodity,  first  in  the  shape  of  his  own  commodity,  then  in 
^  the  form  of  the  money  for  which  he  exchanged  it,  and  lastly, 
/''  in  the  shape  of  the  commodity  he  buys  with  that  money. 
^^This  change  of  form  does  not  imply  a  change  in  the  magnitude 
of  the  value.  But  the  change,  which  the  value  of  the 
commodity  undergoes  in  this  process,  is  limited  to  a  change  in 
its  money  form.  This  form  exists  first  as  the  price  of  the  com- 
modity offered  for  sale,  then  as  an  actual  sum  of  money,  which, 
however,  was  already  expressed  in  the  price,  and  lastly,  as  the 
price  of  an  equivalent  commodity.  This  change  of  form  no 
more  implies,  taken  alone,  a  change  in  the  quantity  of  value, 
than  does  the  change  of  a  £5  note  into  sovereigns,  half  sove- 
reigns and  shillings.  So  far  therefore  as  the  circulation  of 
commodities  effects  a  change  in  the  form  alone  of  their  values, 
and  is  free  from  disturbing  influences,  it  must  be  the  exchange 
of  equivalents.  Little  as  Vulgar-Economy  knows  about  the 
nature  of  value,  yet  whenever  it  wishes  to  consider  the 
phenomena  of  circulation  in  their  purity,  it  assumes  that  supply 
and  demand  are  equal,  which  amounts  to  this,  that  their  effect 
J  is  nil.  If  therefore,  as  regards  the  use- values  exchanged,  both 
buyer  and  seller  may  possibly  gain  something,  this  is  not  the 
case  as  regards  the  exchange  values.  Here  we  must  rather  say* 
"  Where  equality  exists  there  can  be  no  gain."  ^  It  is  true, 
commodities  may  be  sold  at  prices  deviating  from  their  values, 
but  these  deviations  are  to  be  considered  as  infractions  of  the 
laws  of  the  exchange  of  commodities,"  which  in  its  normal 
state  is  an  exchange  of  equivalents,  consequently,  no  method 
for  increasing  value.^ 

Hence,  we  see  that  behind  all  attempts  to  represent  the 

1  "Dove  d  egualit^  non  d  lucro."  (Galiani,  "Delia  Moneta  in  Custodi,  Parte 
Moderna,"  t.  iv.  p.  244.) 

2  "  L'ccliange  devient  d^savautageux  pour  I'une  des  parties,  lorsque  quelque  chose 
efcrangere  vient  diminuer  ou  exagerer  le  i)rix  ;  alors  I'cgalite  est  bless6e,  mais  la  lesion 
precede  de  cette  cause  et  non  de  I'echange."     ("  Le  Trosne,"  1.  c.  p.  904.) 

3  "L'echange  est  de  sa  nature  un  contrat  d'egalite  qui  se  fait  de  valeur  pour  valeur 
egale.  II  n'est  done  pas  un  moyen  de  s'enrichir,  isuisque  I'on  donne  autant  que  Ton 
resoit."    C"  Le  Trosne,"  L  c.  p.  903.) 


Contradictions  in  the  Foi^mula  of  Capital,     137 


1  Condillac  :  "  Le  Commerce  et  le  Gouveriiemeut "  (1776).  Edit,  Daire  et  Molinari 
in  the  "Melanges  d'Econ.  Polit."    Paris,  1847,  p.  267,  etc. 

2  LeTrosne,  therefore,  answers  his  friend  Condillac  with  justice  as  follows:  "Dans 
vine .  . .  society  formee  il  n'y  a  pas  de  surabondant  en  aucun  genre."  At  the  same  time, 
in  a  bantering  way,  he  remarks  :  "If  both  the  persons  who  exchange  receive  more 
to  an  equal  amount,  and  part  with  less  to  an  equal  amount,  they  both  get  the  same." 
It  is  because  Condillac  has  not  the  remotest  idea  of  the  nature  of  exchange -value 
that  he  has  been  chosen  by  Herr  Professor  Wilhelm  Koscher  as  a  proper  person 
to  answer  for  the  soundness  of  his  own  childish  notions.  See  Roscher's  "Die  Grund- 
lagen  der  Nationalokonomie,  Dritte  Auflage,"  J  858. 


T 


^ 


circulation  of  commodities  as  a  source  of  surplus-value,  there 
lurks  a  quid  pro  quo,  a  mixing  up  of  use-value  and  exchange- 
value.  For  instance,  Condillac  says :  "  It  is  not  true  that  on 
an  exchange  of  commodities  we  give  value  for  value.  On  the 
contrary,  each  of  the  two  contracting  parties  in  every  case, 
gives  a  less  for  a  greater  value.  ...  If  we  really  exchanged 
equal  values,  neither  party  could  make  a  profit.  And  yet,  they 
both  gain,  or  ought  to  gain.  Why  ?  The  value  of  a  thing 
consists  solely  in  its  relation  to  our  wants.  What  is  more  to 
the  one  is  less  to  the  other,  and  vice  versd.  ...  It  is  not  to  be 
assumed  that  we  oficr  for  sale  articles  required  for  our  own 
consumption.  .  .  .  We  wish  to  part  with  a  useless  thing,  in 
order  to  get  one  that  we  need ;  we  want  to  give  less  for  more. 
...  It  was  natural  to  think  that,  in  an  exchange,  value  was 
given  for  value,  whenever  each  of  the  articles  exchanged  was 
of  equal  value  with  the  same  quantity  of  gold.  .  .  .  But  there 
is  another  point  to  be  considered  in  our  calculation.  The 
question  is,  whether  we  both  exchange  something  superfluous 
for  something  necessary."  ^  We  see  in  this  passage,  how  Con- 
dillac not  only  confuses  use-value  with  exchange-value,  but 
in  a  really  childish  manner  assumes,  that  in  a  society,  in  which 
the  production  of  commodities  is  well  developed,  each  producer 
produces  his  own  means  of  subsistence,  and  throws  into  circu- 
lation only  the  excess  over  his  own  requirements.^  Still, 
Condillac's  argument  is  frequently  used  by  modern  economists, 
more  especially  when  the  point  is  to  show,  that  the  exchange 
of  commodities  in  its  developed  form,  commerce,  is  productive  *  V 
of  surplus- value.  For  instance,  "  Commerce  ....  adds  value  to  ^ 

products,  for  the  same  products  in  the  hands  of  consumers,  are  ja 

worth  more  than  in  the  hands  of  producers,  and  it  may  strictly       p  nJ 


^ 


^ 


138  Capitalist  Production, 

be  considered  an  act  of  production."  ^  But  commodities  are  not 
paid  for  twice  over,  once  on  account  of  their  use- value,  and 
again  on  account  of  their  value.  And  though  the  use-value  of 
a  commodity  is  more  serviceable  to  the  buyer  than  to  the 
seller,  its  money  form  is  more  serviceable  to  the  seller.  Would 
he  otherwise  sell  it?  We  might  therefore  just  as  well  say 
that  the  buyer  performs  "  strictly  an  act  of  production,"  by 
converting  stockings,  for  example,  into  money. 

If  commodities, or  commodities  and  money, of  equal  exchange- 
value,  and  consequently  equivalents,  are  exchanged,  it  is  plain 
that  no  one  abstracts  more  value  from,  than  he  throws  into, 
circulation.  There  is  no  creation  of  surplus-value.  And,  in 
its  normal  form,  the  circulation  of  commodities  demands  the 
exchange  of  equivalents.  But  in  actual  practice,  the  process 
does  not  retain  its  normal  form.  Let  us,  therefore,  assume  an 
exchange  of  non-equivalents. 

In  any  case  the  market  for  commodities  is  only  frequented 
by  owners  of  commodities,  and  the  power  which  these  persons! 
exercise  over  each  other,  is  no  other  than  the  power  of  their] 
commodities.  The  material  variety  of  these  commodities  is 
the  material  incentive  to  the  act  of  exchange,  and  makes 
buyers  and  sellers  mutually  dependent,  because  none  of  them 
possesses  the  object  of  his  own  wants,  and  each  holds  in  his 
hand  the  object  of  another's  wants.  Besides  these  material 
differences  of  their  use- values,  there  is  only  one  other  difference 
between  commodities,  namely,  that  between  their  bodily  form 
and  the  form  into  which  they  are  converted  by  sale,  the  differ- 
ence between  commodities  and  money.  And  consequently  the 
owners  of  commodities  are  distinguishable  only  as  sellers,  those 
who  own  commodities,  and  buyers,  those  who  own  money. 

Suppose  then,  that  by  some  inexplicable  privilege,  the  seller 
is  enabled  to  sell  his  commodities  above  their  value,  what  is 
worth  100  for  110,  in  which  case  the  price  is  nominally  raised 
10%.  The  seller  therefore  pockets  a  surplus  value  of  10. 
But  after  he  has  sold  he  becomes  a  buyer.  A  third  owner  of 
commodities  comes  to  him  now  as  seller,  who  in  this  capacity 
also  enjoys  the  privilege  of  selling  his  commodities  10%  too 

1  S.  p.  Newman:  "Elements  of  Polit.  Econ."  Andover  and  New  York,  1835,  p.  175. 


Contradictions  in  the  Fornnula  of  Capital,      139 

dear.  Our  friend  gained  10  as  a  seller  onl}?-  to  lose  it  again  as 
a  buyer.^  The  nett  result  is,  that  all  owners  of  commodities 
sell  their  goods  to  one  another  at  10%  above  their  value,  which 
comes  precisely  to  the  same  as  if  they  sold  them  at  their  true 
value.  Such  a  general  and  nominal  rise  of  prices  has  the  same 
effect  as  if  the  values  had  been  expressed  in  weight  of  silver 
instead  of  in  weight  of  gold.  The  nominal  prices  of  com- 
modities would  rise,  but  the  real  relation  between  their  values 
would  remain  unchanged. 

Let  us  make  the  opposite  assumption,  that  the  buyer  has 
the  privilege  of  purchasing  commodities  under  their  value. 
In  this  case  it  is  no  longer  necessary  to  bear  in  mind  that  he 
in  his  turn  will  become  a  seller.  He  was  so  before  he  became 
buyer ;  he  had  already  lost  10%  in  selling  before  he  gained 
10%  as  buyer.^     Everything  is  just  as  it  was. 

The  creation  of  surplus- value,  and  therefore  the  conversion 
of  money  into  capital,  can  consequently  be  explained  neither 
on  the  assumption  that  commodities  are  sold  above  their  value, 
nor  that  they  are  bought  below  their  value.^ 

The  problem  is  in  no  way  simplified  by  introducing  irrele- 
vant matters  after  the  manner  of  Col.  Torrens  :  "  Effectual 
demand  consists  in  the  power  and  inclination  (!),  on  the  part  of 
consumers,  to  give  for  commodities,  either  by  immediate  or 
circuitous  barter,  some  greater  portion  of .  .  .  capital  than  their 
production  costs."  ^  In  relation  to  circulation,  producers  and 
consumers  meet  only  as  buyers  and  sellers.  To  assert  that  the 
surplus-value  acquired  by  the  producer  has  its  origin  in  the 
fact  that  consumers  pay  for  commodities  more  than  their  value, 

1  "By  the  augmentation  of  the  nominal  value  of  the  produce  .  .  .  sellers  not  en. 
riched  .  .  .  since  what  they  gain  as  sellers,  they  precisely  expend  in  the  quality  of 
buyers."  ("  The  Essential  Principles  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations,"  &c.,  London,  1797, 
p.  66.) 

2  "  Si  I'on  est  force  de  donner  pour  18  livres  une  quantit6  de  telle  production  qui 
en  valait  24,  lorsqu'on  employera  ce  m6me  argent  ^  acheter,  on  aura  6galement  pour 
18  1.  ce  que  I'on  payait  24."    ("  Le  Trosne,"  1.  c.  p.  897.) 

8  "  Chaque  vendeur  ne  peut  done  parvenir  h.  rencherir  habituellement  ses  marchan- 
dises,  qu'en  se  soumettant  aussi  si  payer  habituellement  plus  cher  les  marchandises 
des  autres  vendeurs  ;  et  par  la  meme  raison,  chaque  consommateur  ne  peut  payer 
habituellement  moins  cher  ce  qu'il  achete,  qu'en  se  soumettant  aussi  ^  une  diminu- 
tion semblable  sur  le  prix  des  choses  qu'il  vend."  ("  Mercier  de  la  Kividre, "  1.  c.  p.  555.) 

4  K.  Torrens  :  *' An  Essay  on  the  Production  of  Wealth."    London,  1821,  p.  349. 


140  Capitalist  Production, 

is  only  to  say  in  other  words  :  Tiie  owner  of  commodities  pos- 
sesses, as  a  seller,  the  privilege  of  selling  too  dear.  The  seller 
has  himself  produced  the  commodities  or  represents  their  pro- 
ducer, but  the  buyer  has  to  no  less  extent  produced  the  com- 
modities represented  by  his  money,  or  represents  their  pro- 
ducer. The  distinction  between  them  is,  that  one  buys  and 
the  other  sells.  The  fact  that  the  owner  of  the  commodities, 
under  the  designation  of  producer,  sells  them  over  their  value, 
and  under  the  designation  of  consumer,  pays  too  much  for 
them,  does  not  carry  us  a  single  step  further.^ 

To  be  consistent  therefore,  the  upholders  of  the  delusion  that 
surplus- value  has  its  origin  in  a  nominal  rise  of  prices  or  in  the 
privilege  which  the  seller  has  of  selling  too  dear,  must  assume 
the  existence  of  a  class  that  only  buys  and  does  not  sell,  i.e., 
only  consumes  and  does  not  produce.  The  existence  of  such  a 
class  is  inexplicable  from  the  standpoint  we  have  so  far  reached, 
viz.,  that  of  simple  circulation.  But  let  us  anticipate.  The 
money  with  which  such  a  class  is  constantly  making  purchases, 
must  constantly  flow  into  their  pockets,  without  any  exchange, 
gratis,  by  might  or  right,  from  the  pockets  of  the  commodity- 
owners  themselves.  To  sell  commodities  above  their  value  to 
such  a  class,  is  only  to  crib  back  again  a  part  of  the  money 
previously  given  to  it.^  The  towns  of  Asia  Minor  thus  paid  a 
3^early  money  tribute  to  ancient  Rome.  With  this  money 
Rome  purchased  from  them  commodities,  and  purchased  them 
too  dear.  The  provincials  cheated  the  Romans,  and  thus  got 
back  from  their  conquerors,  in  the  course  of  trade,  a  portion  of 
the  tribute.  Yet,  for  all  that,  the  conquered  were  the  really 
cheated.  Their  goods  were  still  paid  for  with  their  own  money. 
That  is  not  the  way  to  get  rich  or  to  create  surplus-value. 

Let  us  therefore  keep  within  the  bounds  of  exchange  where 

1  "The  idea  of  profits  being  paid  by  the  consumers,  is,  assuredly,  very  absurd.  Who 
are  the  consumers  ?  "  (G.Ramsay:  "AnEssay  on  the  Distribution  of  Wealth."  Edin- 
burgh, 1836,  p.  183.) 

2  "  When  a  man  is  in  want  of  a  demand,  does  Mr.  Malthus  recommend  him  to  pay 
some  other  person  to  take  off  his  goods?"  is  a  question  put  by  an  angry  disciple  of 
Ricardo  to  Malthus,  who,  like  his  disciple.  Parson  Chalmers,  economically  glorifies 
this  class  of  simple  buyers  or  consumers.  (See  ' '  An  Inquiry  into  those  principles  re- 
specting the  Nature  of  Demand  and  the  necessity  of  Consumption,  lately  advocated 
by  Mr.  Malthus,"  &c.     Lond.,  1821,  p.  55.) 


Contradictions  in  the  Formula  of  Capital,      141 

sellers  are  also  buyers,  and  buyers,  sellers.  Our  difficulty  may 
perhaps  have  arisen  from  treating  the  actors  as  personifications 
instead  of  as  individuals. 

A  may  be  clever  enough  to  get  the  advantage  of  B  or  C 
without  their  being  able  to  retaliate.  A  sells  wine  worth  £40 
to  B,  and  obtains  from  him  in  exchange  corn  to  the  value  of 
j650.  a  has  converted  his  £40  into  £50,  has  made  more  money 
out  of  less,  and  has  converted  his  commodities  into  capital. 
Let  us  examine  this  a  little  more  closely.  Before  the  exchange 
we  had  £40  worth  of  wine  in  the  hands  of  A,  and  £50  worth 
of  corn  in  those  of  B,  a  total  value  of  £90.  After  the  exchange 
we  have  still  the  same  total  value  of  £90.  The  value  in  circula- 
tion has  not  increased  by  one  iota,  it  is  only  distributed  differ- 
ently between  A  and  B.  What  is  a  loss  of  value  to  B  is  surplus- 
value  to  A ;  what  is  "  minus  "  to  one  is  "  plus  "  to  the  other. 
The  same  change  would  have  taken  place,  if  A,  without  the 
formality  of  an  exchange,  had  directly  stolen  the  £10  from  B. 
The  sum  of  the  values  in  circulation  can  clearly  not  be  aug- 
mented by  any  change  in  their  distribution,  any  more  than 
the  quantity  of  the  precious  metals  in  a  country  by  a  Jew 
selling  a  Queen  Ann's  farthing  for  a  guinea.  The  capitalist 
class,  as  a  whole,  in  any  country,  cannot  over-reach  themselves. 

Turn  and  twist  then  as  we  may,  the  fact  remains  unaltered. 
If  equivalents  arc  exchanged,  no  surplus-value  results,  and  if 
non-equivalents  are  exchanged,  still  no  surplus- value.^  Circula- 
tion, or  the  exchange  of  commodities,  begets  no  value.^ 

1  Destutt  de  Tracy,  although,  or  perhaps  because,  he  was  a  member  of  the  Institute, 
held  the  ojDposite  view.  He  says,  industrial  capitalists  make  profits  because  "they 
all  sell  for  more  than  it  has  cost  to  produce.  And  to  whom  do  they  sell  ?  In  the 
first  instance  to  one  another."    (1.  c,  p.  239.) 

2  "  L'echange  qui  se  fait  de  deux  valeurs  egales  n'augmente  ni  ne  diminue  la  masse 
des  valeurs  subsistantes  dans  la  societ6.  L'echange  de  deux  valeurs  inegales  .  .  . 
ne  change  rien  non  jdIus  d  la  somme  des  valeurs  sociales,  bien  qu'il  ajoute  £i  la  fortune 
de  I'un  ce  qu'il  6te  de  la  fortune  de  I'autre. "  (J.  B.  Say,  1.  c,  1. 1. ,  pp.  344,  345. )  Say , 
not  in  the  least  troubled  as  to  the  consequences  of  this  statement,  borrows  it,  almost 
word  for  word,  from  the  Physiocrats.  The  following  examj^le  will  shew  how  Monsieur 
Say  turned  to  account  the  writings  of  the  Physiocrats,  in  his  day  quite  forgotten,  for 
ihe  purpose  of  expanding  the  *'  value  "  of  his  own.  His  most  celebrated  saying,  "  On 
n'achdte  des  produits  qu'avec  des  produits  "  (1.  c,  t.  II.,  p.  438)  runs  as  follows  in 
the  original  i)hysiocratic  work :  "Les  productions  ne  se  j>aient  qu'avec  des  productions." 
{"LeTrosne,"l.  c,  p.  899.) 

3  "  Exchange  confers  no  value  at  all  upon  products. "  (F.  Way  land :  "  The  Elements 
of  Political  Economy."    Boston,  1853,  p.  168.) 


142  Capitalist  Production. 

The  reason  is  now  therefore  plain  why,  in  analysing  the 
standard  form  of  capital,  the  form  under  which  it  determines 
the  economical  organisation  of  modern  society,  we  entirely 
left  out  of  consideration  its  most  popular,  and,  so  to  say,  ante- 
diluvian forms,  merchants'  capital  and  money-lenders'  capital. 

The  circuit  M — C — M',  buying  in  order  to  sell  dearer,  is  seen 
most  clearly  in  genuine  merchants'  capital.  But  the  movement 
takes  place  entirely  within  the  sphere  of  circulation.  Since, 
however,  it  is  impossible,  by  circulation  alone,  to  account  for 
the  conversion  of  money  into  capital,  for  the  formation  of 
surplus-value,  it  would  appear,  that  merchants'  capital  is  an 
impossibility,  so  long  as  equivalents  are  exchanged;^  that,  there- 
fore, it  can  only  have  its  origin  in  the  twofold  advantage 
gained,  over  both  the  selling  and  the  buying  producers,  by  the 
merchant  who  parasitically  shoves  himself  in  between  them. 
It  is  in  this  sense  that  Franklin  says,  "  war  is  robbery, 
commerce  is  generally  cheating."^  If  the  transformation  of 
merchants'  money  into  capital  is  to  be  explained  otherwise 
than  by  the  producers  being  simply  cheated,  a  long  series  of 
intermediate  steps  would  be  necessary,  which,  at  present,  when 
the  simple  circulation  of  commodities  forms  our  only  assump- 
tion, are  entirely  wanting. 

What  we  have  said  with  reference  to  merchants'  capital, 
applies  still  more  to  money-lenders'  capital.  In  merchants' 
capital,  the  two  extremes,  the  money  that  is  thrown  upon  the 
market,  and  the  augmented  money  that  is  withdrawn  from  the 
market,  are  at  least  connected  by  a  purchase  and  a  sale,  in 
other  words  by  the  movement  of  the  circulation.  In  money- 
lenders' capital  the  form  M — C — M'  is  reduced  to  the  two  ex- 
tremes without  a  mean,  M — M',  money  exchanged  for  more 
money,  a  form  that  is  incompatible  with  the  nature  of  money, 
and  therefore  remains  inexplicable  from  the  standpoint  of  the 
circulation  of  commodities.     Hence  Aristotle :  "  since  chrema- 

1  Under  the  rule  of  invariable  equivalents  commerce  would  be  imi^ossible.  (G. 
Opdyke:  "  A  Treatise  on  Polit.  Economy."  New  York,  1851,  p.  66-69.)  "  The  difference 
between  real  value  and  exchange  value  is  based  upon  this  fact,  namely,  that  the 
value  of  a  thing  is  different  from  the  so-called  equivalent  given  for  it  in  trade,  i.e., 
that  this  equivalent  is  no  equivalent."    (F.  Engels,  1.  c.  p.  96.) 

2  Benjamin  Franklin  :  Works,  Vol.  II.  edit.  Sparks  in  "Positions  to  be  examined 
concerning  National  Wealth,"  p.  376. 


Contradictions  in  the  Formida  of  Capital.      143 

tistic  is  a  double  science,  one  part  belonging  to  commerce,  the 
other  to  economic,  the  latter  being  necessary  and  praiseworthy, 
the  former  based  on  circulation  and  with  justice  disapproved 
(for  it  is  not  based  on  Nature,  but  on  mutual  cheating),  there- 
fore the  usurer  is  most  rightly  hated,  because  money  itself  is 
the  source  of  his  gain,  and  is  not  used  for  the  purposes  for 
which  it  was  invented.  For  it  originated  for  the  exchange  of 
commodities,  but  interest  makes  out  of  money,  more  money. 
Hence  its  name  {roxoi  interest  and  offspring).  For  the  be- 
gotten are  like  those  who  beget  them.  But  interest  is  money 
of  money,  so  that  of  all  modes  of  making  a  living,  this  is  the 
most  contrary  to  nature."^ 

In  the  course  of  our  investigation,  we  shall  find  that  both 
merchants'  capital  and  interest-bearing  capital  are  derivative 
forms,  and  at  the  same  time  it  will  become  clear,  why  these 
two  forms  appear  in  the  course  of  history  before  the  modern 
standard  form  of  capital. 

We  have  shown  that  surplus-value  cannot  be  created  by 
circulation,  and,  therefore,  that  in  its  formation,  something 
must  take  place  in  the  background,  which  is  not  apparent  in 
the  circulation  itself^  But  can  surplus- value  possibly  originate 
■anywhere  else  than  in  circulation,  which  is  the  sum  total  of  all 
the  mutual  relations  of  commodity-owners,  as  far  as  they  are 
determined  by  their  commodities  ?  Apart  from  circulation, 
the  commodity-owner  is  in  relation  only  with  his  own  com- 
modity. So  far  as  regards  value,  that  relation  is  limited  to 
this,  that  the  commodity  contains  a  quantity  of  his  own  labour, 
that  quantity  being  measured  by  a  definite  social  standard. 
This  quantity  is  expressed  by  the  value  of  the  commodity,  and 
since  the  value  is  reckoned  in  money  of  account,  this  quantity 
is  also  expressed  by  the  price,  which  we  will  suppose  to  be  £10. 
But  his  labour  is  not  represented  both  by  the  value  of  the 
commodity,  and  by  a  surplus  over  that  value,  not  by  a  price  of 
10  that  is  also  a  price  of  11,  not  by  a  value  that  is  greater  than 
itself.     The  commodity  owner  can,  by  his  labour,  create  value, 

^  Aristotle,  1.  c.  c.  10. 

^"  Profit,  in  the  usual  condition  of  the  market,  is  not  made  by  exchanging.  Had 
it  not  existed  before,  neither  could  it  after  that  transaction,"    (Eamsay,  1.  c,  p,  184. 


144  Capitalist  Production. 

but  not  self-expanding  value.  He  can  increase  the  value  of  his 
commodity,  by  adding  fresh  labour,  and  therefore  more  value 
to  the  value  in  hand,  by  making,  for  instance,  leather  into 
boots.  The  same  material  has  now  more  value,  because  it 
contains  a  greater  quantity  of  labour.  The  boots  have  there- 
fore more  value  than  the  leather,  but  the  value  of  the  leather 
remains  what  it  was  ;  it  has  not  expanded  itself,  has  not, 
during  the  making  of  the  boots,  annexed  surplus  value.  It  is 
therefore  impossible  that  outside  the  sphere  of  circulation,  a 
producer  of  commodities  can,  without  coming  into  contact  with 
other  commodity  owners,  expand  value,  and  consequently  con- 
vert money  or  commodities  into  capital. 

It  is  therefore  impossible  for  capital  to  be  produced  by  cir- 
culation, and  it  is  equally  impossible  for  it  to  originate  apart 
from  circulation.  It  must  have  its  origin  both  in  circulation 
and  yet  not  in  circulation. 

We  have,  therefore,  got  a  double  result. 

The  conversion  of  money  into  capital  has  to  be  explained  on 
the  basis  of  the  laws  that  regulate  the  exchange  of  commodities, 
in  such  a  way  that  the  starting  point  is  the  exchange  of 
equivalents.^  Our  friend.  Moneybags,  who  as  yet  is  only  an 
embryo  capitalist,  must  buy  his  commodities  at  their  value, 
must  sell  them  at  their  value,  and  yet  at  the  end  of  the  pro- 
cess must  withdraw  more  value  from  circulation  than  he  threw 


1  From  the  foregoing  investigation,  the  reader  will  see  that  this  statement  only  means 
that  the  formation  of  capital  must  be  possible  even  though  the  price  and  value  of  a 
commodity  be  the  same  ;  for  its  formation  cannot  be  attributed  to  any  deviation  of 
the  one  from  the  other.  If  prices  actually  differ  from  values,  we  must,  first  of  all, 
reduce  the  former  to  the  latter,  in  other  words,  treat  the  difference  as  accidental  in 
order  that  the  phenomena  may  be  observed  in  their  purity,  and  our  observations  not 
interfered  with  by  disturbing  circumstances  that  have  nothing  to  do  with  the  process 
in  question.  We  know,  moreover,  that  this  reduction  is  no  mere  scientific  i^rocess. 
The  continual  oscillations  in  prices,  their  rising  and  falling,  compensate  each  other, 
and  reduce  themselves  to  an  average  price,  which  is  their  hidden  regulator.  It  forms 
the  guiding  star  of  the  merchant  or  the  manufacturer  in  every  undertaking  that  re- 
quires time.  He  knows  that  when  a  long  period  of  time  is  taken,  commodities  are 
sold  neither  over  nor  under,  but  at  their  average  price.  If  therefore  he  thought  about 
the  matter  at  all,  he  would  formulate  the  problem  of  the  formation  of  capital  as 
follows :  How  can  we  account  for  the  origin  of  capital  on  the  supposition  that  prices 
are  regulated  by  the  average  j)rice,  i.e.,  ultimately  by  the  value  of  the  commodities? 
I  say  "  ultimately,"  because  average  prices  do  not  directly  coincide  with  the  values  of 
commodities,  as  Adam  Smith,  Kicardo,  and  others  believe. 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power,     145 

into  it  at  starting.  His  development  into  a  full-grown  capi- 
talist must  take  place,  both  within  the  sphere  of  circulation 
and  without  it.  These  are  the  conditions  of  the  problem. 
Hie  Rhodus,  hie  salta  ! 


CHAPTER  VI. 

THE  BUYING  AND  SELLING  OF  LABOUR-POWER. 

The  change  of  value  that  occurs  in  the  case  of  money  intended 
to  be  converted  into  capital,  cannot  take  place  in  the  money 
itself,  since  in  its  function  of  means  of  purchase  and  of  pay- 
ment, it  does  no  more  than  realise  the  price  of  the  commodity 
it  buys  or  pays  for ;  and,  as  hard  cash,  it  is  value  petrified, 
never  varying.^  Just  as  little  can  it  originate  in  the  second 
act  of  circulation,  the  re-sale  of  the  commodity,  which  does 
no  more  than  transform  the  article  from  its  bodily  form  back 
again  into  its  money-form.  The  change  must,  therefore,  take 
place  in  the  commodity  bought  by  the  first  act,  M — C,  but  not 
in  its  value,  for  equivalents  are  exchanged,  and  the  commodity 
is  paid  for  at  its  full  value.  We  are,  therefore,  forced  to  the 
conclusion  that  the  change  originates  in  the  use-value,  as  such, 
of  the  commodity,  i.e.,  in  its  consumption.  In  order  to  be  able 
to  extract  value  from  the  consumption  of  a  commodity,  our 
friend,  Moneybags,  must  be  so  lucky  as  to  find,  within  the 
sphere  of  circulation,  in  the  market,  a  commodity,  whose  use- 
value  possesses  the  peculiar  property  of  being  a  source  of 
value,  whose  actual  consumption,  therefore,  is  itself  an  em- 
bodiment of  labour,  and,  consequently,  a  creation  of  value. 
The  possessor  of  money  does  find  on  the  market  such  a  special 
commodity  in  capacity  for  labour  or  labour-power. 

By  labour-power  or  capacity  for  labour  is  to  be  understood 
the  aggregate  of  those  mental  and  physical  capabilities  exist- 
ing in  a  human  being,  which  he  exercises  whenever  he 
produces  a  use-value  of  any  description. 

1  "  In  the  form  of  money capital  is  productive  of  no  profit."     (Ricardo  :. 

"  Princ.  of  Pol.  Econ."  p.  267.) 

K 


14^  Capitalist  Production. 

But  in  order  that  our  owner  of  money  may  be  able  to  find 
labour-power  offered  for  sale  as  a  commodity,  various  conditions 
must  first  be  fulfilled.  The  exchange  of  commodities  of  itself 
implies  no  other  relations  of  dependence  than  those  which 
result  from  its  own  nature.  On  this  assumption,  labour-power 
can  appear  upon  the  market  as  a  commodity,  only  if,  and  so 
far  as,  its  possessor,  the  individual  whose  labour-power  it  is, 
offers  it  for  sale,  or  sells  it,  as  a  commodity.  In  order  that  he 
may  be  able  to  do  this,  he  must  have  it  at  his  disposal,  must 
be  the  untrammelled  owner  of  his  capacity  for  labour,  i.e.,  of 
his  person.^  He  and  the  owner  of  money  meet  in  the  market, 
and  deal  with  each  other  as  on  the  basis  of  equal  rights,  with 
this  difierence  alone,  that  one  is  buyer,  the  other  seller ;  both, 
therefore,  equal  in  the  eyes  of  the  law.  The  continuance  of 
this  relation  demands  that  the  owner  of  the  labour-power 
should  sell  it  only  for  a  definite  period,  for  if  he  were  to  sell  it 
rump  and  stump,  once  for  all,  he  would  be  selling  himself, 
converting  himself  from  a  free  man  into  a  slave,  from  an  owner 
of  a  commodity  into  a  commodity.  He  must  constantly  look 
upon  his  labour-power  as  his  own  property,  his  own  commodity, 
and  this  he  can  only  do  by  placing  it  at  the  disposal  of  the  buyer 
temporarily,  for  a  definite  period  of  time.  By  this  means  alone 
can  he  avoid  renouncing  his  rights  of  ownership  over  it.^ 

1  In  encyclopaedias  of  classical  antiquities  we  find  such  nonsense  as  this — that  in 
the  ancient  world  capital  was  fuUy  developed,  "  except  that  the  free  labourer  and  a 
system  of  credit  was  wanting."  Mommsen  also,  in  his  "History  of  B-ome,"  commits, 
in  this  respect,  one  blunder  after  another. 

2  Hence  legislation  in  various  countries  fixes  a  maximum  for  labour-contracts. 
Wherever  free  labour  is  the  rule,  the  laws  regulate  the  mode  of  terminating  this  con- 
tract. In  some  States,  particularly  in  Mexico  (before  the  American  Civil  War,  also  in 
the  territories  taken  from  Mexico,  and  also,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  in  the  Danubian 
provinces  till  the  revolution  effected  by  Kusa),  slavery  is  hidden  \mder  the  form  of 
jpeonage.  By  means  of  advances,  repayable  in  labour,  which  are  handed  down 
from  generation  to  generation,  not  only  the  individual  labourer,  but  his  family, 
Ijecome,  de  facto,  the  property  of  other  persons  and  their  families.  Juarez  abolished 
peonage.  The  so-called  Emperor  Maximilian  re-established  it  by  a  decree,  which,  in 
the  House  of  Eepresentativ^es  at  Washington,  was  aptly  denounced  as  a  decree  for  the 
re-introduction  of  slavery  into  Mexico.  "  I  may  make  over  to  another  the  use, 
for  a  limited  time,  of  my  particular  bodily  and  mental  aptitudes  and  cajjabilities ; 
because,  in  consequence  of  this  restriction,  they  are  impressed  with  a  character  of 
alienation  with  regard  to  me  as  a  whole.  But  by  the  alienation  of  all  my  labour- 
time  and  the  whole  of  my  work,  I  should  be  converting  the  substance  itself,  in  other 
words,  my  general  activity  and  reality,  my  person,  into  the  property  of  another. " 
(Hegel,  "  Philosophie  des  Rechts."    Berlin,  1840,  p.  104  §  67.) 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour- Power,     147 

The  second  essential  condition  to  the  owner  of  money 
finding  labour-power  in  the  market  as  a  commodity  is  this — 
that  the  labourer  instead  of  being  in  the  position  to  sell  com- 
modities in  which  his  labour  is  incorporated,  must  be  obliged 
to  offer  for  sale  as  a  commodity  that  very  labour-power,  which 
exists  only  in  his  living  self. 

In  order  that  a  man  may  be  able  to  sell  commodities  other 
than  labour-power,  he  must  of  course  have  the  means  of 
production,  as  raw  material,  implements,  &c.  No  boots  can 
be  made  without  leather.  He  requires  also  the  means  of 
subsistence.  Nobody — not  even  "  a  musician  of  the  future  " — 
can  live  upon  future  products,  or  upon  use-values  in  an  un- 
finished state ;  and  ever  since  the  first  moment  of  his  appearance 
on  the  world's  stage,  man  always  has  been,  and  must  still  be 
a  consumer,  both  before  and  while  he  is  producing.  In  a 
society  where  all  products  assume  the  form  of  commodities, 
these  commodities  must  be  sold  after  they  have  been  produced ; 
it  is  only  after  their  sale  that  they  can  serve  in  satisfying  the 
requirements  of  their  producer.  The  time  necessary  for  their 
sale  is  superadded  to  that  necessary  for  their  production. 

For  the  conversion  of  his  money  into  capital,  therefore,  the 
owner  of  money  must  meet  in  the  market  with  the  free 
labourer,  free  in  the  double  sense,  that  as  a  free  man  he  can 
dispose  of  his  labour-power  as  his  own  commodity,  and  that  on 
the  other  hand  he  has  no  other  commodity  for  sale,  is  short 
of  everything  necessary  for  the  realisation  of  his  labour- 
power. 

The  question  why  this  free  labourer  confronts  him  in  the 
market,  has  no  interest  for  the  owner  of  money,  who  regards 
the  labour  market  as  a  branch  of  the  general  market  for  com- 
modities. And  for  the  present  it  interests  us  just  as  little. 
We  cling  to  the  fact  theoretically,  as  he  does  practically.  One 
thing,  however,  is  clear — nature  does  not  produce  on  the  one 
side  owners  of  money  or  commodities,  and  on  the  other  men 
possessing  nothing  but  their  own  labour-power.  This  relation 
has  no  natural  basis,  neither  is  its  social  basis  one  that  is 
common  to  all  Listorical  periods.  It  is  clearly  the  result  of 
past  historical  development,  the  product  of  many  economical 


il      \ 


148  Capitalist  Production. 

revolutions,  of  the  extinction  of  a  whole  series  of  older  forms 
of  social  production. 

So,  too,  the  economical  categories,  already  discussed  by  us, 
bear  the  stamp  of  history.  Definite  historical  conditions  are 
necessary  that  a  product  may  become  a  commodity.  It  must 
not  be  produced  as  the  immediate  means  of  subsistence  of  the 
producer  himself.  Had  we  gone  further,  and  inquired  under 
what  circumstances  all,  or  even  the  majority  of  products  take 
the  form  of  commodities,  we  should  have  found  that  this  can 
only  happen  with  production  of  a  very  specific  kind,  capitalist 
production.  Such  an  inquiry,  however,  would  have  been 
foreign  to  the  analysis  of  commodities.  Production  and 
circulation  of  commodities  can  take  place,  although  the  great 
mass  of  the  objects  produced  are  intended  for  the  immediate 
requirements  of  their  producers,  are  not  turned  into  commodi- 
ties, and  consequently  social  production  is  not  yet  by  a  long 
way  dominated  in  its  length  and  breadth  by  exchange-value. 
The  appearance  of  products  as  commodities  presupposes  such  a 
development  of  the  social  division  of  labour,  that  the  separation 
of  use-value  from  exchange-value,  a  separation  which  first 
begins  with  barter,  must  already  have  been  completed.  But 
such  a  degree  of  development  is  common  to  many  forms  of 
society,  which  in  other  respects  present  the  most  varying 
historical  features.  On  the  other  hand,  if  we  consider  money, 
its  existence  implies  a  definite  stage  in  the  exchange  of 
commodities.  The  particular  functions  of  money  which  it 
performs,  either  as  the  mere  equivalent  of  commodities,  or  as 
means  of  circulation,  or  means  of  payment,  as  hoard  or  as 
universal  money,  point,  according  to  the  extent  and  relative 
preponderance  of  the  one  function  or  the  other,  to  ver}^ 
different  stages  in  the  process  of  social  production.  Yet  we 
know  by  experience  that  a  circulation  of  commodities  relatively 
primitive,  suflfices  for  the  production  of  all  these  forms.  Other- 
wise with  capital.  The  historical  conditions  of  its  existence 
are  by  no  means  given  with  the  mere  circulation  of  money  and 
commodities.  It  can  spring  into  life,  only  when  the  owner  of 
the  means  of  production  and  subsistence  meets  in  the  market 
with  the  free  labourer  selling  his  labour-power.     And  this  one 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power,     149 

historical  condition  comprises  a  world's  history.  Capital, 
therefore,  announces  from  its  first  appearance  a  new  epoch  in 
the  process  of  social  production.  ^ 

We  must  now  examine  more  closely  this  peculiar  commodity, 
labour-power.  Like  all  others  it  has  a  value.  ^  How  is  that 
value  determined  ? 

The  value  of  labour-power  is  determined,  as  in  the  case  of 
every  other  commodity,  by  the  labour-time  necessary  for  the 
production,  and  consequently  also  the  reproduction,  of  this 
special  article.  So  far  as  it  has  value,  it  represents  no  more 
than  a  definite  quantity  of  the  average  labour  of  society 
incorporated  in  it.  Labour-power  exists  only  as  a  capacity,  5r 
power  of  the  living  individual.  Its  production  consequently 
presupposes  his  existence.  Given  the  individual,  the  produc- 
tion of  labour-power  consists  in  his  reproduction  of  himself  or 
his  maintenance.  For  his  maintenance  he  requires  a  given 
quantity  of  the  means  of  subsistence.  Therefore  the  labour- 
time  requisite  for  the  production  of  labour-power  reduces  itself 
to  that  necessary  for  the  production  of  those  means  of 
subsistence ;  in  other  words,  the  value  of  labour-power  is  the 
value  of  the  means  of  subsistence  necessary  for  the  mainten- 
ance of  the  labourer.  Labour-power,  however,  becomes  a 
reality  only  by  its  exercise ;  it  sets  itself  in  action  only  by 
working.  But  thereby  a  definite  quantity  of  human  muscle, 
nerve,  brain,  &c.,  is  wasted,  and  these  require  to  be  restored. 
This  increased  expenditure  demands  a  larger  income.  ^  If  the 
owner  of  labour-power  works  to-day,  to-morrow  he  must  again 
be  able  to  repeat  the  same  process  in  the  same  conditions  as 
regards  health  and  strength.  His  means  of  subsistence  must 
therefore  be  sufficient  to  maintain  him  in  his  normal  state  as 

1  The  capitalist  epoch  is  therefore  characterised  by  this,  that  labour-power  takes 
in  the  eyes  of  the  labourer  himself  the  form  of  a  commodity  which  is  his  property  ; 
his  labour  consequently  becomes  wage  labour.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  only  from 
this  moment  that  the  produce  of  labour  universally  becomes  a  commodity. 

2  "  The  value  or  worth  of  a  man,  is  as  of  all  other  things  his  price — that  is  to  say, 
so  much  as  would  be  given  for  the  use  of  his  power. "  (Th.  Hobbes :  "  Leviathan  "  in 
Works,  Ed.  Molesworth.     Lond.  1839-44,  v.  iii.,  p.  76.) 

3  Hence  the  Roman  Villicus,  as  oveilooker  of  the  agricultural  slaves,  received 
"more  meagre  fare  than  working  slaves,  because  his  work  was  lighter."  (Th. 
Mommsen  Rom.  Geschichte,  1856,  p.  810.) 


150  Capitalist  Production, 

a  labouring  individual.  His  natural  wants,  such  as  food, 
clothing,  fuel,  and  housing,  vary  according  to  the  climatic  and 
other  physical  conditions  of  his  country.  On  the  other  hand, 
the  number  and  extent  of  his  so-called  necessary  wants,  as  also 
the  modes  of  satisfying  them,  are  themselves  the  product  of 
historical  development,  and  depend  therefore  to  a  great  extent 
on  the  degree  of  civilisation  of  a  country,  more  particularly  on 
the  conditions  under  which,  and  consequently  on  the  habits  and 
degree  of  comfort  in  which,  the  class  of  free  labourers  has  been 
formed.  ^  In  contradistinction  therefore  to  the  case  of  other 
commodities,  there  enters  into  the  determination  of  the  value 
of  labour-power  a  historical  and  moral  element.  Nevertheless, 
in  a  given  country,  at  a  given  period,  the  average  quantity  of 
the  means  of  subsistence  necessary  for  the  labourer  is 
practically  known. 

The  owner  of  labour-power  is  mortal.  If  then  his  appear- 
ance in  the  market  is  to  be  continuous,  and  the  continuous  con- 
version of  money  into  capital  assumes  this,  the  seller  of  labour- 
power  must  perpetuate  himself,  "  in  the  way  that  every  living 
individual  perpetuates  himself,  by  procreation."^  The  labour- 
power  withdrawn  from  the  market  by  wear  and  tear  and 
death,  must  be  continually  replaced  by,  at  the  very  least,  an 
equal  amount  of  fresh  labour-power.  Hence  the  sum  of  the 
means  of  subsistence  necessary  for  the  production  of  labour- 
power  must  include  the  means  necessary  for  the  labourer's 
substitutes,  i.e.,  his  children,  in  order  that  this  race  of  peculiar 
commodity-owners  may  perpetuate  its  appearance  in  the 
market.^ 

In  order  to  modify  the  human  organism,  so  that  it  may  ac- 
quire skill  and  handiness  in  a  given  branch  of  industry,  and 
become  labour-power  of  a  special  kind,  a  special  education  or 
training  is  requisite,  and  this,  on  its  part,  costs  an  equivalent 

1  Compare  W.  H.  Thornton :  "  Overpopulation  and  its  Remedy,"  Lond.,  1846. 

2  Petty. 

3  "  Its  (labour's)  natural  price.  .  .  .  consists  in  such  a  quantity  of  necessaries 
rind  comforts  of  life,  as,  from  the  nature  of  the  climate,  and  the  habits  of  the  coun- 
try, are  necessary  to  support  the  labourer,  and  to  enable  him  to  rear  such  a  family 
as  may  preserve,  in  the  market,  an  undiminished  supply  of  labour."  (R.  Torrens  : 
"An  Essay  on  the  external  Corn  Trade."  Lond.,  1815,  p.  62.)  The  word  labour  is 
here  wrongly  used  for  labour-power. 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power.     1 5 1 

in  commodities  of  a  greater  or  less  amount.  This  amount 
varies  according  to  the  more  or  less  complicated  character  of 
the  labour-power.  The  expenses  of  this  education  (excessively- 
small  in  the  case  of  ordinary  labour-power),  enter  pro  tanto 
into  the  total  value  spent  in  its  production.  # 

The  value  of  labour-power  resolves  itself  into  the  value  of  a 
definite  quantity  of  the  means  of  subsistence.     It  therefore  ^ 

varies  with  the  value  of  these  means  or  with  the  quantity  of      .  -i 
labour  requisite  for  their  production.  \\ 

Some  of  the  means  of  subsistence,  such  as  food  and  fuel,  are  ^ 
consumed  daily,  and  a  fresh  supply  must  be  provided  '^si. 
daily.       Others     such    as    clothes     and    furniture     last    for  ^^ 

longer  periods  and  require  to  be  replaced  only  at  longer  in- 
tervals. One  article  must  be  bought  or  paid  for  daily,  another 
weekly,  another  quarterly,  and  so  on.  But  in  whatever  way 
the  sum  total  of  these  outlays  may  be  spread  over  the  year, 
they  must  be  covered  by  the  average  income,  taking  one  day 
with  another.  If  the  total  of  the  commodities  required  daily 
for  the  production  of  labour-power=A,  and  those  required 
weekly=B,  and  those  required  quarterly=C,  and  so  on,  the 
daily  average  of  these  commodities  =  ^^+^^^^^+^*'-  Suppose 
that  in  this  mass  of  commodities  requisite  for  the  average  day 
there  are  embodied  6  hours  of  social  labour,  then  there  is  incor- 
porated daily  in  labour-power  half  a  day's  average  social  labour, 
in  other  words,  half  a  day's  labour  is  requisite  for  the  daily 
production  of  labour-power.  This  quantity  of  labour  forms 
the  value  of  a  day's  labour-power  or  the  value  of  the  labour- 
power  daily  reproduced.  If  half  a  day's  average  social  labour  is 
incorporated  in  three  shillings,  then  three  shillings  is  the  price 
corresponding  to  the  value  of  a  day's  labour-power.  If  its 
owner  therefore  offers  it  for  sale  at  three  shillings  a  day,  its 
selling  price  is  equal  to  its  value,  and  according  to  our  sup- 
position, our  friend  Moneybags,  who  is  intent  upon  converting 
his  three  shillings  into  capital,  pays  this  value. 

The  minimum  limit  of  the  value  of  labour-power  is  de- 
termined by  the  value  of  the  commodities,  without  the  daily 
supply  of  which  the  labourer  cannot  renew  his  vital  energy, 
consequently  by  the  value  of  those  means  of  subsistence  that 


152  Capitalist  Production, 

are  physically  indispensable.  If  the  price  of  labour-power  fall 
to  this  minimum,  it  falls  below  its  value,  since  under  such  cir- 
cumstances it  can  be  maintained  and  developed  only  in  a 
crippled  state.  But  the  value  of  every  commodity  is  deter- 
mined by  the  labour-time  requisite  to  turn  it  out  so  as  to  be  of 
normal  quality. 

It  is  a  very  cheap  sort  of  sentimentality  which  declares  this 
method  of  determining  the  value  of  labour-power,  a  method 
prescribed  by  the  very  nature  of  the  case,  to  be  a  brutal 
method,  and  which  wails  with  Rossi  that,  "To  comprehend 
capacity  for  labour  (puissance  de  travail)  at  the  same  time 
that  we  make  abstraction  from  the  means  of  subsistence  of  the 
labourers  during  the  process  of  production,  is  to  comprehend  a 
phantom  (^tre  de  raison).  When  we  speak  of  labour,  or 
capacity  for  labour,  we  speak  at  the  same  time  of  the  labourer 
and  his  means  of  subsistence,  of  labourer  and  wages."^  When 
we  speak  of  capacity  for  labour,  we  do  not  speak  of  labour,  any 
more  than  when  we  speak  of  capacity  for  digestion,  we  speak 
of  digestion.  The  latter  process  requires  something  more  than 
a  good  stomach.  When  we  speak  of  capacity  for  labour,  we  do 
not  abstract  from  the  necessary  means  of  subsistence.  On  the 
contrary,  their  value  is  expressed  in  its  value.  If  his  capacity 
for  labour  remains  unsold,  the  labourer  derives  no  benefit  from 
it,  but  rather  he  will  feel  it  to  be  a  cruel  nature-imposed 
necessity  that  this  capacity  has  cost  for  its  production  a  de- 
finite amount  of  the  means  of  subsistence  and  that  it  will  con- 
tinue to  do  so  for  its  reproduction.  He  will  then  agree  with 
Sismondi :  "  that  capacity  for  labour.  ...  is  nothing  unless  it 
is  sold."" 

One  consequence  of  the  peculiar  nature  of  labour-power  as  a 
commodity  is,  that  its  use-value  does  not,  on  the  conclusion  of 
the  contract  between  the  buyer  and  seller,  immediately  pass 
into  the  hands  of  the  former.  Its  value,  like  that  of  every 
other  commodity,  is  already  fixed  before  it  goes  into  circula- 
tion, since  a  definite  quantity  of  social  labour  has  been  spent 
upon  it ;  but  its  use- value  consists  in  the  subsequent  exercise  of 

1  Rossi.     "  Cours  d'Econ.  Polit :  "  Bruxelles,  1842,  p.  370. 

2  Sismondi :  "  Nouv.  Princ.  etc,"  1. 1,  p.  112. 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power,     153 

its  force.  The  alienation  of  labour-power  and  its  actual  appro- 
priation by  the  buyer,  its  employment  as  a  use-value,  are 
separated  by  an  interval  of  time.  But  in  those  cases  in  which 
the  formal  alienation  by  sale  of  the  use-value  of  a  commodity,  is 
not  simultaneous  with  its  actual  delivery  to  the  buyer,  the 
money  of  the  latter  usually  functions  as  means  of  payment.^ 
In  every  country  in  which  the  capitalist  mode  of  production 
reigns,  it  is  the  custom  not  to  pay  for  labour-power  before  it 
has  been  exercised  for  the  period  fixed  by  the  contract,  as  for 
example,  the  end  of  each  week.  In  all  cases,  therefore,  the  use- 
value  of  the  labour-power  is  advanced  to  the  capitalist  :  the 
labourer  allows  the  buyer  to  consume  it  before  he  receives  pay- 
ment of  the  price ;  he  everywhere  gives  credit  to  the 
capitalist.  That  this  credit  is  no  mere  fiction,  is  shown  not 
only  by  the  occasional  loss  of  wages  on  the  bankruptcy  of  the 
capitalist,  ^  but  also  by  a  series  of  more  enduring  conse- 
quences.^    Nevertheless,  whether  money  serves  as  a  means  of 

^  "  All  labour  is  paid  after  it  has  ceased."  ("  An  Inquiry  into  those  Principles  re- 
specting the  Nature  of  Demand,"  &c.,  p.  104.)  "  Le  credit  commercial  a  du  commencer 
au  moment  od  I'ouvrier,  premier  artisan  de  la  production,  a  pu,  au  moyen  de  ses 
Economies,  attendre  le  salaire  de  son  travail  jusqu,  si  la  fin  de  la  semaine,  de  la 
quinzaine,  du  mois,  du  trimestre,  &c.  (Ch.  Ganilh  :  '*  Des  Systemes  de  I'Econ.  Polit." 
2eme.  edit.  Paris,  1821,  t.  I.  p.  150.) 

2  "  L'ouvrier  prete  son  industrie,"  but  adds  Storch  slyly  :  he  "  risks  nothing  "  ex- 
cept "de  perdre  son  salaire  ....  l'ouvrier  ne  transmet  rien  de  materiel." 
(Storch :  "  Cours  d'Econ.  Polit.  Econ."    Petersbourg,  1815,  t.  II.,  p.,  37.) 

3  One  example.  In  London  there  are  two  sorts  of  bakers,  the  *'  full  priced,"  who 
sell  bread  at  its  full  value,  and  the  "  undersellers,"  who  sell  it  under  its  value.  The 
latter  class  comprises  more  than  three-fourths  of  the  total  number  of  bakers,  (p. 
xxxii  in  the  Eepoi  t  of  H.  S.  Tremenheere,  commissioner  to  examine  into  ' '  the  griev- 
ances complained  of  by  the  journeymen  bakers,"  &c..  Loud.  1862.)  The  undersellers, 
almost  without  exception,  sell  bread  adulterated  with  alum,  soap,  pearl  ashes,  chalk, 
Derbyshire  stone-dust,  and  such  like  agreeable  nourishing  and  wholesome  ingredients. 
(See  the  above  cited  blue  book,  as  also  the  report  of  "  the  committee  of  1855  on  the 
adulteration  of  bread,"  and  Dr  Hassall's  "  Adulterations  detected,"  2nd  Ed.  Lond. 
1862.)  Sir  JohnOordon  stated  before  the  committee  of  1855,  that  '*in  consequence 
of  these  adulterations,  the  poor  man,  who  lives  on  two  pounds  of  bread  a  day,  docs 
not  now  get  one  fourth  part  of  nourishing  matter,  let  alone  the  deleterious  effects  on 
his  health."  Tremenheere  states  (1.  c.  p.  xlviii),  as  the  reason,  why  a  very  large  part 
of  the  working  class,  although  well  aware  of  this  adulteration,  nevertheless  accept 
the  alum,  stone-dust,  &c.,  as  part  of  their  purchase :  that  it  is  for  them  *'  a  matter  of 
necessity  to  take  from  their  baker  or  from  the  chandler's  shop,  such  bread  as  they 
choose  to  supply. "  As  they  are  not  paid  their  wages  before  the  end  of  the  week, 
they  in  their  turn  are  unable  "  to  pay  for  the  bread  consumed  by  their  families,  dur- 
ing the  week,  before  the  end  of  the  week,"  and  Tremenheere  adds  on  the  evidence  of 
witnesses,  "  it  is  notorious  that  bread  composed  of  those  mixtures,  is  made  expressly 


154  Capitalist  Prodtiction, 

purchase  or  as  a  means  of  payment,  this  makes  no  alteration  in 
the  nature  of  the  exchange  of  commodities.  The  price  of  the 
labour-power  is  fixed  by  the  contract,  although  it  is  not 
realised  till  later,  like  the  rent  of  a  house.  The  labour-power  is 
sold,  although  it  is  only  paid  for  at  a  later  period.  It  will, 
therefore,  be  useful,  for  a  clear  comprehension  of  the  relation 
of  the  parties,  to  assume  provisionally,  that  the  possessor  of 
labour-power,  on  the  occasion  of  each  sale,  immediately  re- 
ceives the  price  stipulated  to  be  paid  for  it. 

We  now  know  how  the  value  paid  by  the  purchaser  to  the 
possessor  of  this  peculiar  commodity,  labour-power,  is  de- 
termined. The  use-value  which  the  former  gets  in  exchange, 
manifests  itself  only  in  the  actual  usufruct,  in  the  consump- 
tion of  the  labour-power.  The  money  owner  buys  every- 
thing necessary  for  this  purpose,  such  as  raw  material,  in  the 
market,  and  pays  for  it  at  its  full  value.  The  consumption  of 
labour-power  is  at  one  and  the  same  time  the  production  of 
commodities  and  of  surplus  value.  The  consumption  of  labour- 
power  is  completed,  as  in  the  case  of  every  other  commodity, 
outside  the  limits  of  the  market  or  of  the  sphere  of  circulation. 
Accompanied  by  Mr.  Moneybags  and  by  the  possessor  of  labour- 
power,  we  therefore  take  leave  for  a  time  of  this  noisy  sphere, 
where  everything  takes  place  on  the  surface  and  in  view  of  all 
men,  and  follow  them  both  into  the  hidden  abode  of  production, 

for  sale  in  this  manner. "  In  many  English  and  still  more  Scotch  agricultural  dis- 
tricts, wages  are  paid  fortnightly  and  even  monthly ;  with  such  long  intervals  between 
the  payments,  the  agricultural  labourer  is  obliged  to  buy  on  credit.  ...  He 
must  pay  higher  prices,  and  is  in  fact  tied  to  the  shop  which  gives  him  credit.  Thus 
at  Horningham  in  Wilts,  for  example,  where  the  wages  are  monthly,  the  same  flour 
that  he  could  buy  elsewhere  at  Is  lOd  per  stone,  costs  him  2s  4d  per  stone.  {"  Sixth 
Report"  on  "Public  Health"  by  "The  Medical  Officer  of  the  Privy  Council. 
&c.,  1864."  p.  264.)  "  The  block  printers  of  Paisley  and  Kilmarnock  enforced,  by 
a  strike,  fortnightly,  instead  of  monthly  payment  of  wages."  ("Eeports  of  the  In- 
spectors of  Factories  for  31st  Oct.,  1853,"  p.  34).  As  a  further  pretty  result  of  the 
credit  given  by  the  workmen  to  the  capitalist,  we  may  refer  to  the  method  current  in 
many  English  coal  mines,  where  the  labourer  is  not  paid  till  the  end  of  the  month, 
and  in  the  meantime,  receives  sums  on  account  from  the  capitalist,  often  in  goods  for 
which  the  miner  is  obliged  to  pay  more  than  the  market  price  (Truck-system.)  "  It  is 
a  common  practice  with  the  coal  masters  to  pay  once  a  month,  and  advance  cash  to 
their  workmen  at  the  end  of  each  intermediate  week.  The  cash  is  given  in  the  shop" 
(i.e.,  the  Tommy  shop  which  belongs  to  the  master) ;  "the  men  take  it  on  one  side 
and  lay  it  out  on  the  other."  ("Children's  Employment  Commission,  III.  Report," 
Lond.  1864,  p.  38,  n.  192.) 


The  Buying  and  Selling  of  Labour-Power,     155 

on  whose  threshold  there  stares  us  in  the  face  "  No  admittance 
except  on  business."  Here  we  shall  see,  not  only  how  capital 
produces,  but  how  capital  is  produced.  We  shall  at  last  force 
the  secret  of  profit  making. 

This  sphere  that  we  are  deserting,  within  whose  boundaries 
the  sale  and  purchase  of  labour-power  goes  on,  is  in  fact  a  very- 
Eden  of  the  innate  rights  of  man.  There  alone  rule  Freedom, 
Equality,  Property  and  Bentham.  Freedom,  because  both  buyer 
and  seller  of  a  commodity,  say  of  labour-power,  are  constrained 
only  by  their  own  free  will.  They  contract  as  free  agents,  and 
the  agreement  they  come  to,  is  but  the  form  in  which  they  give 
legal  expression  to  their  common  will.  Equality,  because  each 
enters  into  relation  with  the  other,  as  with  a  simple  owner  of 
commodities,  and  they  exchange  equivalent  for  equivalent. 
Property,  because  each  disposes  only  of  what  is  his  own.  And 
Bentham,  because  each  looks  only  to  himself.  The  only  force 
that  brings  them  together  and  puts  them  in  relation  with  each 
other,  is  the  selfishness,  the  gain  and  the  private  interests  of 
each.  Each  looks  to  himself  only,  and  no  one  troubles  himself 
about  the  rest,  and  just  because  they  do  so,  do  they  all,  in 
accordance  with  the  pre-established  harmony  of  things,  or 
under  the  auspices  of  an  all-shrewd  providence,  work  together 
to  their  mutual  advantage,  for  the  common  weal  and  in  the 
interest  of  all. 

On  leaving  this  sphere  of  simple  circulation  or  of  exchange 
of  commodities,  which  furnishes  the  "  Free-trader  Vulgaris  " 
with  his  views  and  ideas,  and  with  the  standard  by  which  he 
judges  a  society  based  on  capital  and  wages,  we  think  we  can 
perceive  a  change  in  the  physiognomy  of  our  dramatis  personse. 
He,  who  before  was  the  money  owner,  now  strides  in  front  as 
capitalist ;  the  possessor  of  labour-power  follows  as  his  labourer. 
The  one  with  an  air  of  importance,  smirking,  intent  on  business; 
the  other,  timid  and  holding  back,  like  one  who  is  bringing  his 
own  hide  to  market  and  has  nothing  to  expect  but — a  hiding. 


PART  III. 

THE  PRODUCTION  OF  ABSOLUTE  SURPLUS- 
VALUE. 


CHAPTER  VII. 

THE  LABOUR-PSOCESS  AND    THE  PROCESS    OF    PRODUCING  SUR- 

PLUS-VALUK 

SECTION   1. — THE   LABOUR- PKOCESS   OR   THE   PRODUCTION   OP   USE- VALUES. 

The  capitalist  buys  labour-power  in  order  to  use  it;  and  labour- 
power  in  use  is  labour  itself.  The  purchaser  of  labour-power  con- 
sumes it  by  setting  the  seller  of  it  to  work.  By  working,  the 
latter  becomes  actually,  what  before  he  only  was  potentially, 
labour-power  in  action,  a  labourer.  In  order  that  his  labour  may 
reappear  in  a  commodity,  he  must,  before  all  things,  expend  it 
on  something  useful,  on  something  capable  of  satisfying  a 
want  of  some  sort.  Hence,  what  the  capitalist  sets  the  lab- 
ourer to  produce,  is  a  particular  use- value,  a  specified  article. 
The  fact  that  the  production  of  use- values,  or  goods,  is  carried 
on  under  the  control  of  a  capitalist  and  on  his  behalf,  does  not 
alter  the  general  character  of  that  production.  We  shall, 
therefore,  in  the  first  place,  have  to  consider  the  labour-process 
independently  of  the  particular  form  it  assumes  under  given 
social  conditions. 

Labour  is,  in  the  first  place,  a  process  in  which  both  man 
and  Nature  participate,  and  in  which  man  of  his  own  accord 
starts,  regulates,  and  controls  the  material  re-actions  between 
himself  and  Nature.  He  opposes  himself  to  Nature  as  one  of 
her  own  forces,  setting  in  motion  arms  and  legs,  head   and 


The  Labour  Process, 


157 


hands,  the  natural  forces  of  his  body,  in  order  to  appropriate 
Nature's  productions  in  a  form  adapted  to  his  own  wants.  By 
thus  acting  on  the  external  world  and  changing  it,  he  at  the 
same  time  changes  his  own  nature.  He  develops  his  slumber- 
ing powers  and  compels  them  to  act  in  obedience  to  his  sway. 
We  are  not  now  dealing  with  those  primitive  instinctive  forms 
of  labour  that  remind  us  of  the  mere  animal.  An  immeasur- 
able interval  of  time  separates  the  state  of  things  in  which  a 
man  brings  his  labour-power  to  market  for  sale  as  a  commodity, 
from  that  state  in  which  human  labour  was  still  in  its  first  in- 
stinctive stage.  We  presuppose  labour  in  a  form  that  stamps 
it  as  exclusively  human.  A  spider  conducts  operations  that 
resemble  those  of  a  weaver,  and  a  bee  puts  to  shame  many  an 
architect  in  the  construction  of  her  cells.  But  what  distin- 
guishes the  worst  architect  from  the  best  of  bees  is  this,  that 
the  architect  raises  his  structure  in  imagination  before  he  erects 
it  in  reality.  At  the  end  of  every  labour-process,  we  get  a  re- 
sult that  already  existed  in  the  imagination  of  the  labourer  at 
its  commencement.  He  not  only  effects  a  change  of  form  in 
the  material  on  which  he  works,  but  he  also  realises  a  purpose 
of  his  own  that  gives  the  law  to  his  modus  operandi,  and  to 
which  he  must  subordinate  his  will.  And  this  subordination 
is  no  mere  momentary  act.  Besides  the  exertion  of  the  bodily 
organs,  the  process  demands  that,  during  the  whole  operation, 
the  workman's  will  be  steadily  in  consonance  with  his  purpose. 
This  means  close  attention.  The  less  he  is  attracted  by  the 
nature  of  the  work,  and  the  mode  in  which  it  is  carried  on, 
and  the  less,  therefore,  he  enjoys  it  as  something  which  gives 
play  to  his  bodily  and  mental  powers,  the  more  close  his  atten- 
tion is  forced  to  be. 

The  elementary  factors  of  the  labour-process  are  l,the  personal 
activity  of  man,  i.6.,  work  itself,  2,  the  subject  of  that  work, 
and  3,  its  instruments. 

The  soil  (and  this,  economically  speaking,  includes  water)  in 
the  virgin  state  in  which  it  supplies  ^  man  with  necessaries  or 

1  "The  earth's  spontaneous  productions  being  in  small  quantity,  and  quite  indepen- 
dent of  man,  appear,  as  it  were,  to  be  furnished  by  Nature,  in  the  same  way  as  a  small 
sum  is  given  to  a  young  man,  in  order  to  i^ut  him  in  a  way  of  industry,  and  of  mak- 
ing his  fortune. "  (James  Steuart :  "Principles  of  Polit.  Econ."  edit.  Dublin,  1770, 
V.  I.  p.  116). 


\C^ 


158  Capitalist  Production, 

the  means  of  subsistence  ready  to  hand,  exists  independently 
of  him,  and  is  the  universal  subject  of  human  labour.  All 
those  things  which  labour  merely  separates  from  immediate 
connection  with  their  environment,  are  subjects  of  labour 
spontaneously  provided  by  Nature.  Such  are  fish  which  we 
catch  and  take  from  their  element,  water,  timber  which  we 
fell  in  the  virgin  forest,  and  ores  which  we  extract  from  their 
veins.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  subject  of  labour  has,  so  to 
say,  been  filtered  through  previous  labour,  we  call  it  raw 
material ;  such  is  ore  already  extracted  and  ready  for  wash- 
ing. All  raw  material  is  the  subject  of  labour,  but  not  everj'- 
subject  of  labour  is  raw  material ;  it  can  only  become  so,  after 
it  has  undergone  some  alteration  by  means  of  labour. 

An  instrument  of  labour  is  a  thing,  or  a  complex  of  things, 
which  the  labourer  interposes  between  himself  and  the  subject 
of  his  labour,  and  which  serves  as  the  conductor  of  his  activity. 
He  makes  use  of  the  mechanical,  physical,  and  chemical  pro- 
perties of  some  substances  in  order  to  make  other  substances 
subservient  to  his  aims.^  Leaving  out  of  consideration  such 
ready-made  means  of  subsistence  as  fruits,  in  gathering  which 
a  man's  own  limbs  serve  as  the  instruments  of  his  labour,  the 
first  thing  of  which  the  labourer  possesses  himself  is  not  the 
subject  of  labour  but  its  instrument.  Thus  Nature  becomes  one 
of  the  organs  of  his  activity,  one  that  he  annexes  to  his  own 
bodily  organs,  adding  stature  to  himself  in  spite  of  the  Bible. 
As  the  earth  is  his  original  larder,  so  too  it  is  his  original  tool 
house.  It  supplies  him,  for  instance,  with  stones  for  throwing, 
grinding,  pressing,  cutting,  &c.  The  earth  itself  is  an  instru- 
ment of  labour,  but  when  used  as  such  in  agriculture  implies  a 
whole  series  of  other  instruments  and  a  comparatively  high 
development  of  labour.^     No  sooner  does  labour  undergo  the 

1  ' '  Reason  is  just  as  cunning  as  she  is  powerful.  Her  cunning  consists  principally  in 
her  mediating  activity,  which,  by  causing  objects  to  act  and  re-acfc  on  each  other  in 
accordance  with  their  own  nature,  in  this  way,  without  any  direct  interference  in  the 
process,  carries  out  reason's  intentions."  (Hegel :  "  Encyklopadie,  Erster  Theil.  Die 
Logik."    Berlin,  1840,  p.  382.) 

2  In  his  otherwise  miserable  work,  ("  Theorie  de  I'Econ.  Polit.'"  Paris,  1819), 
Ganilh  enumerates  in  a  striking  manner  in  opposition  to  the  "  Physiocrats  "  the  long 
series  of  previous  processes  necessary  before  agriculture  properly  so  called  can  com- 
mence. 


The  Labour  Process,  159 

least  development,  than  it  requires  specially  prepared  instru- 
ments. Thus  in  the  oldest  caves  we  find  stone  implements  and 
weapons.  In  the  earliest  period  of  human  history  domesticated 
animals,  i.e.,  animals  which  have  been  bred  for  the  purpose,  and 
have  undergone  modifications  by  means  of  labour,  play  the 
chief  part  as  instruments  of  labour  along  with  specially  pre- 
pared stones,  wood,  bones,  and  shells.^  The  use  and  fabrication 
of  instruments  of  labour,  although  existing  in  the  germ  among 
certain  species  of  animals,  is  specifically  characteristic  of  the 
human  labour-process,  and  Franklin  therefore  defines  man  as  a 
tool-making  animal.  Relics  of  by-gone  instruments  of  labour 
possess  the  same  importance  for  the  investigation  of  extinct 
economical  forms  of  society,  as  do  fossil  bones  for  the  determina- 
tion of  extinct  species  of  animals.  It  is  not  the  articles  made, 
but  how  they  are  made,  and  by  what  instruments,  that  enables 
us  to  distinguish  different  economical  epochs.^  Instruments  of 
labour  not  only  supply  a  standard  of  the  degree  of  develop- 
ment to  which  human  labour  has  attained,  but  they  are  also 
indicators  of  the  social  conditions  under  which  that  labour  is 
carried  on.  Among  the  instruments  of  labour,  those  of  a 
mechanical  nature,  which,  taken  as  a  whole,  we  may  call  the 
bone  and  muscles  of  production,  ofi^er  much  more  decided 
characteristics  of  a  given  epoch  of  production,  than  those  which, 
like  pipes,  tubs,  baskets,  jars,  &;c.,  serve  only  to  hold  the 
materials  for  labour,  which  latter  class,  we  may  in  a  general 
way,  call  the  vascular  system  of  production.  The  latter  first 
begins  to  play  an  important  part  in  the  chemical  industries. 

In  a  wider  sense  we  may  include  among  the  instruments  of 
labour,  in  addition  to  those  things  that  are  used  for  directly 
transferring  labour  to  its  subject,  and  which  therefore,  in  one 

1  Turgot  in  his  "  Keflexions  sur  la  Formation  et  la  Distribution  des  Richesses  " 
(1766)  brings  well  into  prominence  the  importance  of  domesticated  animals  to  early 
civilisation. 

2  The  least  important  commodities  of  all  for  the  technological  comparison  of 
different  epochs  of  production  are  articles  of  luxury,  in  the  strict  meaning  of  the  term. 
However  little  our  written  histories  up  to  this  time  notice  the  development  of  material 
production,  which  is  the  basis  of  all  social  life,  and  therefore  of  all  real  history,  yet 
prehistoric  times  have  been  classified  in  accordance  with  the  results,  not  of  so  called 
historical,  but  of  materialistic  investigations.  These  periods  have  been  divided,  to 
corresj)ond  with  the  materials  from  which  their  implements  and  weapons  were  made, 
viz.,  into  the  stone,  the  bronze,  and  the  iron  ages. 


i6o  Capitalist  Production. 

way  or  another,  serve  as  conductors  of  activity,  all  such  objects 
as  are  necessary  for  carrying  on  the  labour-process.  These  do 
not  enter  directly  into  the  process,  but  without  them  it  is  either 
impossible  for  it  to  take  place  at  all,  or  possible  only  to  a 
partial  extent.  Once  more  we  find  the  earth  to  be  a  universal 
instrument  of  this  sort,  for  it  furnishes  a  locus  standi  to  the 
labourer  and  a  field  of  employment  for  his  activity.  Among 
instruments  that  are  the  result  of  previous  labour  and  also 
belong  to  this  class,  we  find  workshops,  canals,  roads,  and  so 
forth. 

In  the  labour-process,  therefore,  man's  activity,  with  the  help 
of  the  instruments  of  labour,  effects  an  alteration,  designed  from 
the  commencement,  in  the  material  worked  upon.  The  process 
disappears  in  the  product ;  the  latter  is  a  use-value.  Nature's 
material  adapted  by  a  change  of  form  to  the  wants  of  man. 
Labour  has  incorporated  itself  with  its  subject :  the  former  is 
materialised,  the  latter  transformed.  That  which  in  the  labourer 
appeared  as  movement,  now  appears  in  the  product  as  a  fixed 
quality  without  motion.  The  blacksmith  forges  and  the  pro- 
duct is  a  forcrinor. 

If  we  examine  the  whole  process  from  the  point  of  view  of 
its  result,  the  product,  it  is  plain  that  both  the  instruments  and 
the  subject  of  labour,  are  means  of  production,^  and  that  the 
labour  itself  is  productive  labour.^ 

Though  a  use-value,  in  the  form  of  a  product,  issues  from 
the  labour-process,  yet  other  use-values,  products  of  previous 
labour,  enter  into  it  as  means  of  production.  The  same  use- 
value  is  both  the  product  of  a  previous  process,  and  a  means  of 
production  in  a  later  process.  Products  are  therefore  not  only 
results,  but  also  essential  conditions  of  labour. 

With  the  exception  of  the  extractive  industries,  in  which 
the  material  for  labour  is  provided  immediately  by  nature, 
such  as  mining,  hunting,  fishing,  and  agriculture  (so  far  as  the 

^  It  appears  paradoxical  to  assert,  that  uncaught  fish,  for  instance,  are  a  means  of 
production  in  the  fishing  industry.  But  hitherto  no  one  has  discovered  the  art  of 
catching  fish  in  waters  that  contain  none. 

2  This  method  of  determining  from  the  standpoint  of  the  labour-process  alone,  what 
is  productive  labour,  is  by  no  means  directly  applicable  to  the  case  of  the  capitalist 
process  of  production. 


The  Labour  P^^ocess.  16 1 

latter  is  confined  to  breaking  up  virgin  soil),  all  branches  of 
industry  manipulate  raw  material,  objects  already  filtered 
through  labour,  already  products  of  labour.  Such  is  seed  in 
agriculture.  Animals  and  plants,  which  we  are  accustomed  to 
consider  as  products  of  nature,  are  in  their  present  form,  not 
only  products  of,  say  last  year's  labour,  but  the  result  of  a 
gradual  transformation,  continued  through  many  generations, 
under  man's  superintendence,  and  by  means  of  his  labour. 
But  in  the  great  majority  of  cases,  instruments  of  labour  show 
even  to  the  most  superficial  observer,  traces  of  the  labour  of 
past  ages. 

Raw  material  may  either  form  the  principal  substance  of  a 
product,  or  it  may  enter  into  its  formation  only  as  an  acces- 
sory. An  accessory  may  be  consumed  by  the  instruments  of 
labour,  as  coal  under  a  boiler,  oil  by  a  wheel,  hay  by  draft- 
horses,  or  it  may  be  mixed  with  the  raw  material  in  order  to 
produce  some  modification  thereof,  as  chlorine  into  unbleached 
linen,  coal  with  iron,  dye-stuff"  with  wool,  or  again,  it  may  help 
to  carry  on  the  work  itself,  as  in  the  case  of  the  materials  used 
for  heating  and  lighting  workshops.  The  distinction  between 
principal  substance  and  accessory  vanishes  in  the  true  chemical 
industries,  because  there  none  of  the  raw  material  reappears,  in 
its  original  composition,  in  the  substance  of  the  product.^ 

Every  object  possesses  various  properties,  and  is  thus  capable 
of  being  applied  to  different  uses.  One  and  the  same  product 
may  therefore  serve  as  raw  material  in  very  different  processes. 
Corn,  for  example,  is  a  raw  material  for  millers,  starch-manu- 
facturers, distillers,  and  cattle-breeders.  It  also  enters  as  raw 
material  into  its  own  production  in  the  shape  of  seed :  coal,  too, 
is  at  the  same  time  the  product  of,  and  a  means  of  production 
in,  coal-mining. 

Again,  a  particular  product  may  be  used  in  one  and  the  same 
process,  both  as  an  instrument  of  labour  and  as  raw  material. 
Take,  for  instance,  the  fattening  of  cattle,  where  the  animal  is 
the  raw  material,  and  at  the  same  time  an  instrument  for  the 
production  of  manure. 

1  Storch  calls  true  raw  materials  "  matieres,"  and  accessory  material  *'  materiaux :  ^* 
Cherbuliez  describes  accessories  as  "matieres  instrumentales." 

L 


1 62  Capitalist  Prodtiction, 

A  product,  though  ready  for  immediate  consumption,  may 
yet  serve  as  raw  material  for  a  further  product,  as  grapes  when 
they  become  the  raw  material  for  wine.  On  the  other  hand, 
labour  may  give  us  its  product  in  such  a  form,  that  we  can  use 
it  only  as  raw  material,  as  is  the  case  with  cotton,  thread,  and 
yarn.  Such  a  raw  material,  though  itself  a  product,  may  have 
to  go  through  a  whole  series  of  different  processes  :  in  each  of 
these  in  turn,  it  serves,  with  constantly  varying  form,  as  raw 
material,  until  the  last  process  of  the  series  leaves  it  a  perfect 
product,  ready  for  individual  consumption,  or  for  use  as  an  in- 
strument of  labour. 

Hence  we  see,  that  whether  a  use-value  is  to  be  regarded  as 
raw  material,  as  instrument  of  labour,  or  as  product,  this  is  deter- 
mined entirely  by  its  function  in  the  labour  process,  by  the 
position  it  there  occupies  :  as  this  varies,  so  does  its  character. 

Whenever  therefore  a  product  enters  as  a  means  of  produc- 
tion into  a  new  labour-process,  it  thereby  loses  its  character  of 
product,  and  becomes  a  mere  factor  in  the  process.  A  spinner 
treats  spindles  only  as  implements  for  spinning,  and  flax  only 
as  the  material  that  he  spins.  Of  course  it  is  impossible  to  spin 
without  material  and  spindles  ;  and  therefore  the  'existence  of 
these  things  as  products,  at  the  commencement  of  the  spinning 
operation,  must  be  presumed  :  but  in  the  process  itself,  the  fact 
that  they  are  products  of  previous  labour,  is  a  matter  of  utter 
indifference ;  just  as  in  the  digestive  process,  it  is  of  no  impor- 
tance whatever,  that  bread  is  the  produce  of  the  previous 
labour  of  the  farmer,  the  miller,  and  the  baker.  On  the  con- 
trary, it  is  generally  by  their  imperfections  as  products,  that 
the  means  of  production  in  any  process  assert  themselves  in 
their  character  of  products.  A  blunt  knife  or  weak  thread 
forcibly  remind  us  of  Mr.  A.,  the  cutler,  or  Mr.  B.,  the  spinner. 
In  the  finished  product  the  labour  by  means  of  which  it  has 
acquired  its  useful  qualities  is  not  palpable,  has  apparently 
vanished. 

A  machine  which  does  not  serve  the  purposes  of  labour,  is 
useless.  In  addition,  it  falls  a  prey  to  the  destructive  influence 
of  natural  forces.  Iron  rusts  and  wood  rots.  Yarn  with  which 
we  neither  weave  nor  knit,  is  cotton  wasted.     Living  labour 


The  Labour  Process,  163 

must  seize  upon  these  things  and  rouse  them  from  their  death- 
sleep,  change  them  from  mere  possible  use-values  into  real 
and  effective  ones.  Bathed  in  the  fire  of  labour,  appropriated 
as  part  and  parcel  of  labour's  organism,  and,  as  it  were,  made 
alive  for  the  performance  of  their  functions  in  the  process,  they 
are  in  truth  consumed,  but  consumed  with  a  purpose,  as 
elementary  constituents  of  new  use- values,  of  new  products, 
ever  ready  as  means  of  subsistence  for  individual  consumption, 
or  as  means  of  production  for  some  new  labour-process. 

If  then,  on  the  one  hand,  finished  products  are  not  only 
results,  but  also  necessary  conditions,  of  the  labour-process,  on 
the  other  hand,  their  assumption  into  that  process,  their  contact 
with  living  labour,  is  the  sole  means  by  which  they  can  be 
made  to  retain  their  character  of  use-values,  and  be  utilised. 

Labour  uses  up  its  material  factors,  its  subject  and  its 
instruments,  consumes  them,  and  is  therefore  a  process  of  con- 
sumption. Such  productive  consumption  is  distinguished 
from  individual  consumption  by  this,  that  the  latter  uses  up 
products,  as  means  of  subsistence  for  the  living  individual;  the 
former,  as  means  whereby  alone,  labour,  the  labour-power  of 
the  living  individual,  is  enabled  to  act.  The  product,  therefore, 
of  individual  consumption,  is  the  consumer  himself ;  the  result 
of  productive  consumption,  is  a  product  distinct  from  the  con- 
sumer. 

In  so  far  then,  as  its  instruments  and  subjects  are  themselves 
products,  labour  consumes  products  in  order  to  create  products, 
or  in  other  words,  consumes  one  set  of  products  by  turning 
them  into  means  of  production  for  another  set.  But,  just  as  in 
the  beginning,  the  only  participators  in  the  labour-process 
were  man  and  the  earth,  which  latter  exists  independently  of 
man,  so  even  now  we  still  employ  in  the  process  many  means 
of  production,  provided  directly  by  nature,  that  do  not  represent 
any  combination  of  natural  substances  with  human  labour. 

The  labour  process,  resolved  as  above  into  its  simple 
elementary  factors,  is  human  action  with  a  view  to  the  pro- 
duction of  use- values,  appropriation  of  natural  substances  to 
human  requirements  ;  it  is  the  necessary  condition  for  effecting 
exchange  of  matter  between  man  and  Nature ;  it  is  the  ever- 


164  Capitalist  Production. 

lasting  nature-imposed  condition  of  human  existence,  and 
therefore  is  independent  of  every  social  phase  of  that  existence, 
or  rather,  is  common  to  every  such  phase.  It  was,  therefore, 
not  necessary  to  represent  our  labourer  in  connexion  with 
other  labourers ;  man  and  his  labour  on  one  side,  Nature  and 
its  materials  on  the  other,  sufficed.  As  the  taste  of  the  porridge 
does  not  tell  you  who  grew  the  oats,  no  more  does  this  simple 
process  tell  you  of  itself  what  are  the  social  conditions  under 
which  it  is  taking  place,  whether  under  the  slave-owner's 
brutal  lash,  or  the  anxious  eye  of  the  capitalist,  whether 
Cincinnatus  carries  it  on  in  tilling  his  modest  farm  or  a  savage 
in  killing  wild  animals  with  stones.^ 

Let  us  now  return  to  our  would-be  capitalist.  We  left  him 
just  after  he  had  purchased,  in  the  open  market,  all  the  necessary 
factors  of  the  labour-process;  its  objective  factors,  the  means  of 
production,  as  well  as  its  subjective  factor,  labour-power. 
With  the  keen  eye  of  an  expert,  he  has  selected  the  means  of 
production  and  the  kind  of  labour-power  best  adapted  to  his 
particular  trade,  be  it  spinning,  bootmaking,  or  any  other  kind. 
He  then  proceeds  to  consume  the  commodity,  the  labour-power 
that  he  has  just  bought,  by  causing  the  labourer,  the  impersona- 
tion of  that  labour-power,  to  consume  the  mea.ns  of  production 
by  his  labour.  The  general  character  of  the  labour-process  is 
evidently  not  changed  by  the  fact,  that  the  labourer  works  for 
the  capitalist  instead  of  for  himself ;  moreover,  the  particular 
methods  and  operations  employed  in  bootmaking  or  spinning 
are  not  immediately  changed  by  the  intervention  of  the 
capitalist.  He  must  begin  by  taking  the  labour-power  as  he 
finds  it  in  the  market,  and  consequently  be  satisfied  with 
labour  of  such  a  kind  as  would  be  found  in  the  period 
immediately  preceding  the  rise  of  capitalists.  Changes  in  the 
methods  of  production  by  the  subordination  of  labour  to 
capital,  can  take  place  only  at  a  later  period,  and  therefore 
will  have  to  be  treated  of  in  a  later  chapter. 

1  By  a  wonderful  feat  of  logical  acumen,  Colonel  Torrens  has  discovered,  in  this 
stone  of  the  savage  the  origin  of  capital.  "  In  the  first  stone  which  he  [the  savage] 
flings  at  the  wild  animal  he  pursues,  in  the  first  stick  that  he  seizes  to  strike  down 
the  fruit  which  hangs  above  his  reach,  we  see  the  appropriation  of  one  article  for  the 
purpose  of  aiding  in  the  acquisition  of  another,  and  thus  discover  the  origin  of 
capital.     (R.  Torrens  :  "  An  Essay  on  the  Production  of  Wealth,"  &c.,  pp.  70-71.) 


The  Labour  Process,  165 

The  labour-process,  turned  into  the  process  by  which  the 
capitalist  consumes  labour-power,  exhibits  two  characteristic 
phenomena.  First,  the  labourer  works  under  the  control  of 
the  capitalist  to  whom  his  labour  belongs  ;  the  capitalist  taking 
good  care  that  the  work  is  done  in  a  proper  manner,  and  that 
the  means  of  production  are  used  with  intelligence,  so  that 
there  is  no  unnecessary  waste  of  raw  material,  and  no  wear  and 
tear  of  the  implements  beyond  what  is  necessarily  caused  by 
the  work. 

Secondly,  the  product  is  the  property  of  the  capitalist  and 
not  that  of  the  labourer,  its  immediate  producer.  Suppose 
that  a  capitalist  pays  for  a  day's  labour-power  at  its  value  ; 
then  the  right  to  use  that  power  for  a  day  belongs  to  him,  just 
as  much  as  the  right  to  use  any  other  commodity,  such  as  a 
horse  that  he  has  hired  for  the  day.  To  the  purchaser  of  a 
commodity  belongs  its  use,  and  the  seller  of  labour-power,  by 
giving  his  labour,  does  no  more,  in  reality,  than  part  with  the 
use-value  that  he  has  sold.  From  the  instant  he  steps  into 
the  workshop,  the  use- value  of  his  labour-power,  and  therefore 
also  its  use,  which  is  labour,  belongs  to  the  capitalist.  By  the 
purchase  of  labour-power,  the  capitalist  incorporates  labour,  as 
a  living  ferment,  with  the  lifeless  constituents  of  the  product. 
From  his  point  of  view,  the  labour-process  is  nothing  more 
than  the  consumption  of  the  commodity  purchased,  ^.e.,  of 
labour-power;  bub  this  consumption  cannot  be  effected  except 
by  supplying  the  labour-power  with  the  means  of  production. 
The  labour- process  is  a  process  between  things  that  the  capital- 
ist has  purchased,  things  that  have  become  his  property.  The 
product  of  this  process  belongs,  therefore,  to  him,  just  as  much 
as  does  the  wine  which  is  the  product  of  a  process  of  fermenta- 
tion completed  in  his  cellar.^ 

1  "Products  are  appropriated  before  they  are  converted  into  capital ;  this  conver- 
sion does  not  secure  them  from  such  appropriation."  (Cherbuliez  :  *'  Riche  ou  Pauvre," 
edit.  Paris,  1841,  pp.  53,  54.)  "The  Proletarian,  by  selling  his  labour  for  a  definite 
quantity  of  the  necessaries  of  life,  renounces  all  claim  to  a  share  in  the  product. 
The  mode  of  appropriation  of  the  jjroducts  remains  the  same  as  before  ;  it  is  in  no 
way  altered  by  the  bargain  we  have  mentioned.  The  product  belongs  exclusively  to 
the  capitalist,  who  supplied  the  raw  material  and  the  necessaries  of  life  ;  and  this  is 
a  rigorous  consequence  of  the  law  of  appropriation,  a  law  whose  fundamental  prin- 
ciple was  the  very  opposite,  namely,  that  every  labourer  has  an  exclusive  right  to 


1 66  Capitalist  Pi^odtictiori. 


SECTION   2. — THE   PRODUCTIOX   OF   SURPLUS-VALUE. 

The  product  appropriated  by  the  capitalist  is  a  use- value,  as 
yarn,  for  example,  or  boots.  But,  although  boots  are,  in  one 
sense,  the  basis  of  all  social  progress,  and  our  capitalist  is  a 
decided  "  progressist/'  yet  he  does  not  manufacture  boots  for 
their  own  sake.  Use-value  is,  by  no  means,  the  thing  '*  qu'on 
aime  pour  lui-meme  "  in  the  production  of  commodities.  Use- 
values  are  only  produced  by  capitalists,  because,  and  in  so  far 
as,  they  are  the  material  substratum,  the  depositaries  of 
exchange-value.  Our  capitalist  has  two  objects  in  view :  in 
the  first  place,  he  wants  to  produce  a  use-value  that  has  a 
value  in  exchange,  that  is  to  say,  an  article  destined  to  be  sold, 
a  commodity ;  and  secondly,  he  desires  to  produce  a  commodity 
whose  value  shall  be  greater  than  the  sum  of  the  values  of  the 
commodities  used  in  its  production,  that  is,  of  the  means  of 
production  and  the  labour-power,  that  he  purchased  with  his 
good  money  in  the  open  market.  His  aim  is  to  produce  not 
only  a  use- value,  but  a  commodity  also;  not  only  use- value, 
but  value ;  not  only  value,  but  at  the  same  time  surplus- 
value. 

It  must  be  borne  in  mind,  that  we  are  now  dealing  with  the 
production  of  commodities,  and  that,  up  to  this  point,  we  have 
only  considered  one  aspect  of  the  process.  Just  as  commodities 
are,  at  the  same  time,  use- values  and  values,  so  the  process  of 
producing  them  must  be  a  labour-process,  and  at  the  same 
time,  a  process  of  creating  value.^ 

Let  us  now  examine  production  as  a  creation  of  value. 

We  know  that  the  value  of  each  commodity  is  determined 
by  the  quantity  of  labour  expended  on  and  materialised  in  it, 

the  ownership  of  what  he  produces."  (1.  c.  p.  58.)  "When  the  labourers  receive 
wages  for  their  labour  ....  the  capitalist  is  then  the  owner  not  of  the  capital  only  " 
(he  means  the  means  of  production)  "  but  of  the  labour  also.  If  what  is  paid  as  wages 
is  included,  as  it  commonly  is,  in  the  term  capital,  it  is  absurd  to  talk  of  labour 
separately  from  capital.  The  word  capital  as  thus  employed  includes  labour  and 
capital  both."    (James  Mill :  "Elements  of  Pol.  Econ.,"  &c.,  Ed.  1821,  pp.  70,  71.) 

1  As  has  been  stated  in  a  previous  note,  the  English  language  has  two  different 
expressions  for  these  two  different  aspects  of  labour  :  in  the  Simple  Labour-process, 
the  process  of  producing  Use-Values,  it  is  Work  ;  in  the  process  of  creation  of  Value, 
it  is  Labour,  taking  the  term  in  its  strictly  economical  sense. — Ed. 


The  Labou7'  Process.  167 

by  the  working-time  necessary,  under  given  social  conditions, 
for  its  production.  This  rule  also  holds  good  in  the  case  of 
the  product  that  accrued  to  our  capitalist,  as  the  result  of  the 
labour-process  carried  on  for  him.  Assuming  this  product  to 
be  10  lbs.  of  yarn,  our  first  step  is  to  calculate  the  quantity  of 
labour  realised  in  it. 

For  spinning  the  yarn,  raw  material  is  required ;  suppose  in 
this  case  10  lbs.  of  cotton.  We  have  no  need  at  present  to 
investigate  the  value  of  this  cotton,  for  our  capitalist  has,  we 
will  assume,  bought  it  at  its  full  value,  say  of  ten  shillings. 
In  this  price  the  labour  required  for  the  production  of  the 
cotton  is  already  expressed  in  terms  of  the  average  labour  of 
society.  We  will  further  assume  that  the  wear  and  tear  of  the 
spindle,  which,  for  our  present  purpose,  may  represent  all  other 
instruments  of  labour  emploj^ed,  amounts  to  the  value  of  2s. 
If,  then,  twenty-four  hours'  labour,  or  two  working  days,  are 
required  to  produce  the  quantity  of  gold  represented  by  twelve 
shillings,  we  have  here,  to  begin  with,  two -days'  labour  already 
incorporated  in  the  yarn. 

We  must  not  let  ourselves  be  misled  by  the  circumstance 
that  the  cotton  has  taken  a  new  shape  while  the  substance  of 
the  spindle  has  to  a  certain  extent  been  used  up.  ^y  the 
general  law  of  value,  if  the  value  of  40  lbs.  of  yarn  =  the  value 
of  40  lbs.  of  cotton -f- the  value  of  a  whole  spindle,  i.e.^  if  the 
same  working  time  is  required  to  produce  the  commodities  on 
either  side  of  this  equation,  then  10  lbs.  of  yarn  are  an 
equivalent  for  10  lbs.  of  cottoQ,  together  with  one-fourth  of  a 
spindle.  In  the  case  we  are  considering  the  same  working 
time  is  materialised  in  the  10  lbs.  of  yarn  on  the  one  hand, 
and  in  the  10  lbs.  of  cotton  and  the  fraction  ^of  a  spindle 
on  the  other.  Therefore,  whether  value  appears  in  cotton,  in 
a  spindle,  or  in  yarn,  makes  no  difference  in  the  amount  of 
that  value.  The  spindle  and  cotton,  instead  of  resting  quietly 
side  by  side,  join  together  in  the  process,  their  forms  are 
altered,  and  they  are  turned  into  yarn  ;  but  their  value  is 
no  more  affected  by  this  fact  than  it  would  be  if  they  had  been 
simply  exchanged  for  their  equivalent  in  yarn. 

The  labour  required  for  the  production  of  the  cotton,  the 


i68  Capitalist  Production. 

raw  material  of  the  yarn,  is  part  of  the  labour  necessary  to 
produce  the  yarn,  and  is  therefore  contained  in  the  yarn.  The 
same  applies  to  the  labour  embodied  in  the  spindle,  without 
whose  wear  and  tear  the  cotton  could  not  be  spun. 

Hence,  in  determining  the  value  of  the  yarn,  or  the  labour- 
time  required  for  its  production,  all  the  special  processes 
carried  on  at  various  times  and  in  different  places,  which  were 
necessary,  first  to  produce  the  cotton  and  the  wasted  portion  of 
the  spindle,  and  then  with  the  cotton  and  spindle  to  spin  the 
yarn,  may  together  be  looked  on  as  different  and  successive 
phases  of  one  and  the  same  process.  The  whole  of  the  labour 
in  the  yarn  is  past  labour ;  and  it  is  a  matter  of  no  importance 
that  the  operations  necessary  for  the  production  of  its  con- 
stituent elements  were  carried  on  at  times  which,  referred  to 
the  present,  are  more  remote  than  the  final  operation  of 
spinning.  If  a  definite  quantity  of  labour,  say  thirty  days, 
is  requisite  to  build  a  house,  the  total  amount  of  labour  incor- 
porated in  it  is  not  altered  by  the  fact  that  the  work  of  the 
last  day  is  done  twenty-nine  days  later  than  that  of  the  first. 
Therefore  the  labour  contained  in  the  raw  material  and  the 
instruments  of  labour  can  be  treated  just  as  if  it  were  labour 
expended  in  an  earlier  stage  of  the  spinning  process,  before  the 
labour  of  actual  spinning  commenced. 

The  values  of  the  means  of  production,  i.e.,  the  cotton  and  the 
spindle,  which  values  are  expressed  in  the  price  of  twelve 
shillings,  are  therefore  constituent  parts  of  the  value  of  the 
yarn,  or,  in  other  words,  of  the  value  of  the  product. 

Two  conditions  must  nevertheless  be  fulfilled.  First,  the 
cotton  and  spindle  must  concur  in  the  production  of  a  use- 
value  ;  they  must  in  the  present  case  become  yarn.  Value  is 
independent  of  the  particular  use-value  by  which  it  is  borne,  but 
it  must  be  embodied  in  a  use-value  of  some  kind.  Secondly, 
the  time  occupied  in  the  labour  of  production  must  not  exceed 
the  time  really  necessary  under  the  given  social  conditions  of 
the  case.  Therefore,  if  no  more  than  1  lb.  of  cotton  be  requisite 
to  spin  1  lb.  of  yarn,  care  must  be  taken  that  no  more  than 
this  weight  of  cotton  is  consumed  in  the  production  of  1  lb.  of 
yarn ;  and  similarly  with  regard  to  the  spindle.     Though  the 


The  Labour  Process,  169 

capitalist  liave  a  hobby,  and  use  a  gold  instead  of  a  steel 
spindle,  yet  the  only  labour  that  counts  for  anything  in  the 
value  of  the  yarn  is  that  which  would  be  required  to  produce 
a  steel  spindle,  because  no  more  is  necessary  under  the  given 
social  conditions. 

We  now  know  what  portion  of  the  value  of  the  yarn  is  ow- 
ing to  the  cotton  and  the  spindle.  It  amounts  to  twelve 
shillings  or  the  value  of  two  days'  work.  The  next  point  for 
our  consideration  is,  what  portion  of  the  value  of  the  yarn  is 
added  to  the  cotton  by  the  labour  of  the  spinner. 

We  have  now  to  consider  this  labour  under  a  very  different 
aspect  from  that  which  it  had  during  the  labour-process;  there, 
we  viewed  it  solely  as  that  particular  kind  of  human  activity 
which  changes  cotton  into  yarn ;  there,  the  more  the  labour 
was  suited  to  the  work,  the  better  the  yarn,  other  circumstances 
remaining  the  same.  The  labour  of  the  spinner  was  then 
viewed  as  specifically  different  from  other  kinds  of  productive 
labour,  different  on  the  one  hand  in  its  special  aim,  viz.,  spinning, 
different,  on  the  other  hand,  in  the  special  character  of  its 
operations,  in  the  special  nature  of  its  means  of  production  and 
in  the  special  use-value  of  its  product.  For  the  operation  of 
spinning,  cotton  and  spindles  are  a  necessity,  but  for  making 
rifled  cannon  they  would  be  of  no  use  whatever.  Here,  on  the 
contrary,  where  we  consider  the  labour  of  the  spinner  only  so 
far  as  it  is  value-creating,  i.e.,  a  source  of  value,  his  labour  differs 
in  no  respect  from  the  labour  of  the  man  who  bores  cannon,  or 
(what  here  more  nearly  concerns  us),  from  the  labour  of  the 
cotton-planter  and  spindle-maker  incorporated  in  the  means  of 
production.  It  is  solely  by  reason  of  this  identity,  that  cotton 
planting,  spindle  making  and  spinning,  are  capable  of  forming 
the  component  parts,  differing  only  quantitatively  from  each 
other,  of  one  whole,  namely,  the  value  of  the  yarn.  Here,  we 
have  nothing  more  to  do  with  the  quality,  the  nature  and  the 
specific  character  of  the  labour,  but  merely  with  its  quantity. 
And  this  simply  requires  to  be  calculated.  We  proceed  upon 
the  assumption  that  spinning  is  simple,  unskilled  labour,  the 
average  labour  of  a  given  state  of  society.  Hereafter  we  shall 
see  that  the  contrary  assumption  would  make  no  difference. 


170  Capitalist  Production, 

While  the  labourer  is  at  work,  his  labour  constantly  under- 
goes a  transformation :  from  being  motion,  it  becomes  an  object 
without  motion  ;  from  being  the  labourer  working,  it  becomes 
the  thing  produced.  At  the  end  of  one  hour's  spinning,  that 
act  is  represented  by  a  definite  quantity  of  yarn;  in  other 
words,  a  definite  quantity  of  labour,  namely  that  of  one  hour, 
has  become  embodied  in  the  cotton.  We  say  labour,  i.e.y  the  ex- 
penditure of  his  vital  force  by  the  spinner,  and  not  spinning 
labour,  because  the  special  work  of  spinning  counts  here,  only 
so  far  as  it  is  the  expenditure  of  labour-power  in  general,  and 
not  in  so  far  as  it  is  the  specific  work  of  the  spinner. 

In  the  process  we  are  now  considering  it  is  of  extreme  im- 
portance, that  no  more  time  be  consumed  in  the  work  of  trans- 
forming the  cotton  into  yarn  than  is  necessary  under  the  given 
social  conditions.  If  under  normal,  i.e.y  average  social  condi- 
tions of  production,  a  pounds  of  cotton  ought  to  be  made  into 
h  pounds  of  yarn  by  one  hour's  labour,  then  a  day's  labour 
does  not  count  as  12  hours'  labour  unless  12  a  pounds  of  cotton 
have  been  made  into  12  6  pounds  of  yarn ;  for  in  the  creation 
of  value,  the  time  that  is  socially  necessary  alone  counts. 

Not  only  the  labour,  but  also  the  raw  material  and  the  pro- 
duct now  appear  in  quite  a  new  light,  very  different  from  that 
in  which  we  viewed  them  in  the  labour-process  pure  and 
simple.  The  raw  material  serves  now  merely  as  an  absorbent 
of  a  definite  quantity  of  labour.  By  this  absorption  it  is  in 
fact  changed  into  yarn,  because  it  is  spun,  because  labour-power 
in  the  form  of  spinning  is  added  to  it ;  but  the  product,  the 
yarn,  is  now  nothing  more  than  a  measure  of  the  labour 
absorbed  by  the  cotton.  If  in  one  hour  If  lbs.  of  cotton  can  be 
spun  into  If  lbs.  of  yarn,  then  10  lbs.  of  yarn  indicate  the 
absorption  of  6  hours'  labour.  Definite  quantities  of  product, 
these  quantities  being  determined  by  experience,  now  represent 
nothing  but  definite  quantities  of  labour,  definite  masses  of 
crystallized  labour -time.  They  are  nothing  more  than  the 
materialisation  of  so  many  hours  or  so  many  days  of  social 
labour. 

We  are  here  no  more  concerned  about  the  facts,  that  the 
labour  is  the  specific  work  of  spinning,  that  its  subject  is  cotton 


The  Labour  Process,  171 

and  its  product  yarn,  than  we  are  about  the  fact  that  the  subject 
itself  is  already  a  product  and  therefore  raw  material.  If  the 
spinner,  instead  of  spinning,  were  working  in  a  coal  mine,  the 
subject  of  his  labour,  the  coal,  would  be  supplied  by  Nature ; 
nevertheless,  a  definite  quantity  of  extracted  coal,  a  hundred 
weight  for  example,  would  represent  a  definite  quantity  of 
absorbed  labour. 

We  assumed,  on  the  occasion  of  its  sale,  that  the  value  of 
a  day's  labour-power  is  three  shillings,  and  that  six  hours' 
labour  are  incorporated  in  that  sum  ;  and  consequently  that  this 
amount  of  labour  is  requisite  to  produce  the  necessaries  of  life 
daily  required  on  an  average  by  the  labourer.  If  now  our 
spinner  by  working  for  one  hour,  can  convert  If  lbs.  of  cotton 
into  If  lbs.  of  yarn,^  it  follows  that  in  six  hours  he  will  convert 
10  lbs.  of  cotton  into  10  lbs.  of  yarn.  Hence,  during  the  spinn- 
ing process,  the  cotton  absorbs  six  hours'  labour.  The  same 
quantity  of  labour  is  also  embodied  in  a  piece  of  gold  of  the 
value  of  three  shillings.  Consequently  by  the  mere  labour  of 
spinning,  a  value  of  three  shillings  is  added  to  the  cotton. 

Let  us  now  consider  the  total  value  of  the  product,  the  10 
lbs.  of  yarn.  Two  and  a  half  days'  labour  have  been  embodied 
in  it,  of  which  two  days  were  contained  in  the  cotton  and  in 
the  substance  of  the  spindle  worn  away,  and  half  a  day  was 
absorbed  during  the  process  of  spinning.  This  two  and  a  half 
days*  labour  is  also  represented  by  a  piece  of  gold  of  the  value 
of  fifteen  shillings.  Hence,  fifteen  shillings  is  an  adequate  price 
for  the  10  lbs.  of  yarn,  or  the  price  of  one  pound  is  eighteen- 
pence. 

Our  capitalist  stares  in  astonishment.  The  value  of  the  pro- 
duct is  exactly  equal  to  the  value  of  the  capital  advanced.  The 
value  so  advanced  has  not  expanded,  no  surplus-value  has  been 
created,  and  consequently  money  has  not  been  converted  into 
capital.  The  price  of  the  yarn  is  fifteen  shillings,  and  fifteen 
shillings  were  spent  in  the  open  market  upon  the  constituent 
elements  of  the  product,  or,  what  amounts  to  the  same  thing, 
upon  the  factoi-s  of  the  labour-process ;  ten  shillings  were  paid 
for  the  cotton,  two  shillings  for  the  substance  of  the  spindle 

1  These  figures  are  quite  arbitrary. 


172  Capitalist  Production. 

worn  away,  and  three  shillings  for  the  labour-power.  The 
swollen  value  of  the  yarn  is  of  no  avail,  for  it  is  merely  the 
sum  of  the  values  formerly  existing  in  the  cotton,  the  spindle, 
and  the  labour-power  :  out  of  such  a  simple  addition  of  existing 
values,  no  surplus-value  can  possibly  arise.^  These  separate 
values  are  now  all  concentrated  in  one  thing ;  but  so  they  were 
also  in  the  sum  of  fifteen  shillings,  before  it  was  split  up  into 
three  parts,  by  the  purchase  of  the  commodities. 

There  is  in  reality  nothing  very  strange  in  this  result.  The 
value  of  one  pound  of  yarn  being  eighteenpence,  if  our  capitalist 
buys  10  lbs.  of  yarn  in  the  ma^rket,  he  must  pay  fifteen  shillings 
for  them.  It  is  clear  that,  whether  a  man  buys  his  house  ready 
built,  or  gets  it  built  for  him,  in  neither  case  will  the  mode  of 
acquisition  increase  the  amount  of  money  laid  out  on  the 
house. 

Our  capitalist,  who  is  at  home  in  his  vulgar  economy, 
exclaims :  ''  Oh !  but  I  advanced  my  money  for  the  express 
purpose  of  making  more  money."  The  way  to  Hell  is  paved 
with  good  intentions,  and  he  might  just  as  easily  have  intended 
to  make  money,  without  producing  at  all.  *  He  threatens  all 
sorts  of  things.  He  won't  be  caught  napping  again.  In 
future  he  will  buy  the  commodities  in  the  market,  instead  of 
manufacturing  them  himself  But  if  all  his  brother  capitalists 
were  to  do  the  same,  where  would  he  find  his  commodities  in 
the  market  ?  And  his  money  he  cannot  eat.  He  tries  persua- 
sion. "  Consider  my  abstinence ;  I  might  have  played  ducks 
and  drakes  with  the  15  shillings ;  but  instead  of  that  I  con- 
sumed it  productively,  and  made  yarn  with  it."     Very  well, 

1  This  is  the  fundamental  proposition  on  which  is  based  the  doctrine  of  the 
Physiocrats  as  to  the  unproductiveness  of  all  labour  that  is  not  agriculture :  it  is 
irrefutable  for  the  orthodox  economist.  "Cette  fa9on  d'imputer  ^  une  seule  chose 
la  valeur  de  plusieurs  autres  "  (par  exemple  au  lin  la  consommation  du  tisserand), 
* '  d'appliquer,  pour  ainsi  dire,  couche  sur  couche,  plusieurs  valeurs  sur  une  seule,  fait 
que  celle-ci  grossit  d'autant  .  .  .  .  Le  terme  d'addition  peint  tres-bien  la 
maniere  dont  se  forme  le  prix  des  ouvrages  de  main-d'oeuvre;  ce  prix  n'est  qu'un  total 
de  plusieurs  valeurs  consomm^es  et  additionnees  ensemble;  or,  additionner  n'est  pas 
multiplier."    ("  Mercier  de  la  Riviere,"  1.  c,  p.  599.) 

2  Thus  from  1844-47  he  withdrew  part  of  his  capital  from  productive  employment, 
in  order  to  throw  it  away  in  railway  speculations ;  and  so  also,  during  the  American 
Civil  War,  he  closed  his  factory,  and  turned  his  work-people  into  the  streets,  in  order 
to  gamble  on  the  Liverpool  cotton  exchange. 


The  LaboiLT  Process,  173 

and  by  way  of  reward  he  is  now  in  possession  of  good  yarn 
instead  of  a  bad  conscience ;  and  as  for  playing  the  part  of  a 
miser,  it  would  never  do  for  him  to  relapse  into  such  bad  ways 
as  that ;  we  have  seen  before  to  what  results  such  asceticism 
leads.  Besides,  where  nothing  is,  the  king  has  lost  his  rights ; 
whatever  may  be  the  merit  of  his  abstinence,  there  is  nothing 
wherewith  specially  to  remunerate  it,  because  the  value  of  the 
product  is  merely  the  sum  of  the  values  of  the  commodities 
that  were  thrown  into  the  process  of  production.  Let  him 
thei:efore  console  himself  with  the  reflection  that  virtue  is  its 
own  reward.  But  no,  he  becomes  importunate.  He  says: 
"  The  yarn  is  of  no  use  to  me  :  I  produced  it  for  sale."  In  that 
case  let  him  sell  it,  or,  still  better,  let  him  for  the  future  produce^ 
only  things  for  satisfying  his  personal  wants,  a  remedy  that  his 
physician  M'CuUoch  has  already  prescribed  as  infallible  against 
an  epidemic  of  over-production.  He  now  gets  obstinate. 
'*  Can  the  labourer,"  he  asks,  "  merely  with  his  arms  and  legs, 
produce  commodities  out  of  nothing  ?  Did  I  not  supply  him 
with  the  materials,  by  means  of  which,  and  in  which  alone,  his 
labour  could  be  embodied  ?  And  as  the  greater  part  of  society 
consists  of  such  ne'er-do-weels,  have  I  not  rendered  society 
incalculable  service  by  my  instruments  of  production,  my  cotton 
and  my  spindle,  and  not  only  society,  but  the  labourer  also, 
whom  in  addition  I  have  provided  with  the  necessaries  of  life  ? 
And  am  I  to  be  allowed  nothing  in  return  for  all  this  service  ?  " 
Well,  but  has  not  the  labourer  rendered  him  the  equivalent 
service  of  changing  his  cotton  and  spindle  into  yarn  ?  More- 
over, there  is  here  no  question  of  service.  ^  A  service  is  nothing- 
more  than  the  useful  effect  of  a  use-value,  be  it  of  a  commodity, 

1  "  Extol  thyself,  put  on  finery  and  adorn  thyself  .  .  .  but  whoever  takes  more 
or  better  than  he  gives,  that  is  usury,  and  is  not  service,  but  wrong  done  to  his  neigh- 
bour, as  when  one  steals  and  robs.  All  is  not  service  and  benefit  to  a  neighbour  that 
is  called  service  and  benefit.  For  an  adulteress  and  adtdterer  do  one  another  great 
service  and  pleasure.  A  horseman  does  an  incendiary  a  great  service,  by  helloing  him 
to  rob  on  the  highway,  and  pillage  land  and  houses.  The  papists  do  ours  a  great 
service,  in  that  they  don't  drown,  burn,  murder  all  of  them,  or  let  them  all  rot  in 
prison ;  but  let  some  live,  and  only  drive  them  out,  or  take  from  them  what  they 
have.  The  devil  himself  does  his  servants  inestimable  service  ...  To  sum  up, 
the  world  is  full  of  great,  excellent,  and  daily  service  and  benefit."  (Martin  Luther : 
"  An  die  Pfarherrn,  wider  den  Wucher  zu  predigen,"  Wittenberg,  1540.) 


174  Capitalist  Production, 

or  be  it  of  labour.  ^  But  here  we  are  dealing  with  exchange- 
value.  The  capitalist  paid  to  the  labourer  a  value  o£  3  shillings, 
and  the  labourer  gave  him  back  an  exact  equivalent  in  the  value 
of  3  shillings,  added  by  him  to  the  cotton :  he  gave  him  value 
for  value.  Our  friend,  up  to  this  time  so  purse-proud,  suddenly 
assumes  the  modest  demeanour  of  his  own  workman,  and 
exclaims :  "  Have  I  myself  not  worked  ?  Have  I  not  performed 
the  labour  of  superintendence  and  of  overlooking  the  spinner  ? 
And  does  not  this  labour,  too,  create  value  ?"  His  overlooker 
and  his  manager  try  to  hide  their  smiles.  Meanwhile,  after  a 
hearty  laugh,  he  re-assumes  his  usual  mien.  Though  he 
chanted  to  us  the  whole  creed  of  the  economists,  in  reality,  he 
says,  he  would  not  give  a  brass  farthing  for  it.  He  leaves  this 
and  all  such  like  subterfuges  and  juggling  tricks  to  the 
professors  of  political  economy,  who  are  paid  for  it.  He  him- 
self is  a  practical  man ;  and  though  he  does  not  always  consider 
what  he  says  outside  his  business,  yet  in  his  business  he  knows 
what  he  is  about. 

Let  us  examine  the  matter  more  closely.  The  value  of  a 
day's  labour-power  amounts  to  3  shillings,  because  on  our 
assumption  half  a  day's  labour  is  embodied  in  that  quantity  of 
labour-power,  i.e.,  because  the  means  of  subsistence  that  are  daily 
required  for  the  production  of  labour-power,  cost  half  a  day's 
labour.  But  the  past  labour  that  is  embodied  in  the  labour- 
power,  and  the  living  labour  that  it  can  call  into  action  ;  the 
daily  cost  of  maintaining  it,  and  its  daily  expenditure  in  work, 
are  two  totally  different  things.  The  former  determines  the 
exchange- value  of  the  labour-power,  the  latter  is  its  use- value. 
The  fact  that  half  a  day's  labour  is  necessary  to  keep  the 
labourer  alive  during  24  hours,  does  not  in  any  way  prevent 
him  from  working  a  whole  day.  Therefore,  the  value  of  labour- 
power,  and  the  value  which  that  labour-power  creates  in  the 
labour  process,  are  two  entirely  different  magnitudes ;  and  this 
difference  of  the  two  values  was  what  the  capitalist  had  in 
view,  when  he  was  purchasing  the  labour-power.  The  useful 
qualities  that  labour-power  possesses,  and  by  virtue  of  which  it 

1  In  "Zur  Kritik  der  Pol.  Oek.,"  p.  14,  I  make  the  following  remark  on  this 
Ijoint — "  It  is  not  difficult  to  understand  what  '  service '  the  category  '  service '  must 
render  to  a  class  of  economists  like  J.  B.  Say  and  F.  Bastiat." 


The  Labour  Process,  175 

makes  yarn  or  boots,  were  to  him  nothing  more  than  a  conditio 
sine  qua  non;  for  in  order  to  create  vakie,  labour  must  be 
expended  in  a  useful  manner.  What  really  influenced  him  was 
the  specific  use-value  which  this  commodity  possesses  of  being 
a  source  not  only  of  value,  but  of  more  value  than  it  has  itself 
This  is  the  special  service  that  the  capitalist  expects  from 
labour-power,  and  in  this  transaction  he  acts  in  accordance 
with  the  "  eternal  laws  "  of  the  exchange  of  commodities.  The 
seller  of  labour-power,  like  the  seller  of  any  other  commodity, 
realises  its  exchange-value,  and  parts  with  its  use- value.  He 
cannot  take  the  one  without  giving  the  other.  The  use-value 
of  labour-power,  or  in  other  words,  labour,  belongs  just  as  little 
to  its  seller,  as  the  use- value  of  oil  after  it  has  been  sold  belongs 
to  the  dealer  who  has  sold  it.  The  owner  of  the  money  has 
paid  the  value  of  a  day's  labour-power ;  his,  therefore,  is  the 
use  of  it  for  a  day ;  a  day's  labour  belongs  to  him.  The  cir- 
cumstance, that  on  the  one  hand  the  daily  sustenance  of  labour- 
power  costs  only  half  a  day's  labour,  while  on  the  other  hand 
the  very  same  labour-power  can  work  during  a  whole  day,  that 
consequently  the  value  which  its  use  during  one  day  creates,  is 
double  what  he  pays  for  that  use,  this  circumstance  is,  without 
doubt,  a  piece  of  good  luck  for  the  buyer,  but  by  no  means  an 
injury  to  the  seller. 

Our  capitalist  foresaw  this  state  of  things,  and  that  was  the 
cause  of  his  laughter.  The  labourer  therefore  finds,  in  the 
workshop,  the  means  of  production  necessary  for  working,  not 
only  during  six,  but  during  twelve  hours.  Just  as  during  the 
six  hours' process  our  10  lbs.  of  cotton  absorbed  six  hours'  labour, 
and  became  10  lbs.  of  yarn,  so  now,  20  lbs.  of  cotton  will  absorb  12 
hours'  labour  and  be  changed  into  20  lbs.  of  yarn.  Let  us  now 
examine  the  product  of  this  prolonged  process.  There  is  now 
materialised  in  this  20  lbs.  of  yarn  the  labour  of  five  days,  of  which 
four  days  are  due  to  the  cotton  and  the  lost  steel  of  the  spindle, 
the  remaining  day  having  been  absorbed  by  the  cotton  during 
the  spinning  process.  Expressed  in  gold,  the  labour  of  five 
days  is  thirty  shillings.  This  is  therefore  the  price  of  the 
20  lbs.  of  yarn,  giving,  as  before,  eighteenpence  as  the  price  of  a 
pound.     But  the  sum  of  the  values  of  the  commodities  that 


176  Capitalist  Production. 

entered  into  the  process  amounts  to  27  shillings.  The  value 
of  the  yarn  is  30  shillings.  Therefore  the  value  of  the  product 
is  ^  greater  than  the  value  advanced  for  its  production ;  27 
shillings  have  been  transformed  into  30  shillings ;  a  surplus- 
value  of  3  shillings  has  been  created.  The  trick  has  at  last 
succeeded  ;  money  has  been   converted  into  capital. 

Every  condition  of  the  problem  is  satisfied,  while  the  laws 
that  regulate  the  exchange  of  commodities,  have  been  in  no  way 
violated.  Equivalent  has  been  exchanged  for  equivalent.  For 
the  capitalist  as  buyer  paid  for  each  commodity,  for  the  cotton, 
the  spindle  and  the  labour-power,  its  full  value.  He  then  did 
what  is  done  by  every  purchaser  of  commodities;  he  consumed 
their  use- value.  The  consumption  of  the  labour-power,  which 
was  also  the  process  of  producing  commodities,  resulted  in  20 
lbs.  of  yarn,  having  a  value  of  30  shillings.  The  capitalist, 
formerly  a  buyer,  now  returns  to  market  as  a  seller,  of  com- 
modities. He  sells  his  yarn  at  eighteenpence  a  pound,  which  is 
its  exact  value.  Yet  for  all  that  he  withdraws  3  shillings  more 
from  circulation  than  he  originally  threw  into  it.  This 
metamorphosis,  this  conversion  of  money  into  capital,  takes 
place  both  within  the  sphere  of  circulation  and  also  outside  it ; 
within  the  circulation,  because  conditioned  by  the  purchase  of 
the  labour-power  in  the  market ;  outside  the  circulation,  be- 
cause what  is  done  within  it  is  only  a  stepping-stone  to  the 
production  of  surplus- value,  a  process  which  is  entirely  confined 
to  the  sphere  of  production.  Thus  "  tout  est  pour  le  mieux 
dans  le  meilleur  des  mondes  possibles." 

By  turning  his  money  into  commodities  that  serve  as  the 
material  elements  of  a  new  product,  and  as  factors  in  the  labour- 
process,  by  incorporating  living  labour  with  their  dead  sub- 
stance, the  capitalist  at  the  same  time  converts  value,  i.e.,  past, 
materialised,  and  dead  labour  into  capital,  into  value  big  with 
value,  a  live  monster  that  is  fruitful  and  multiplies. 

If  we  now  compare  the  two  processes  of  producing  value  and 
of  creating  surplus-value,  we  see  that  the  latter  is  nothing  but 
the  continuation  of  the  former  beyond  a  definite  point.  If  on 
the  one  hand  the  process  be  not  carried  beyond  the  point, 
where  the  value  paid  by  the  capitalist  for  the  labour-power  is 


The  Labour  Process,  177 

replaced  by  an  exact  equivalent,  it  is  simply  a  process  of  pro- 
ducing value ;  if,  on  the  other  hand,  it  be  continued  beyond 
that  point,  it  becomes  a  process  of  creating  surplus-value. 

If  we  proceed  further,  and  compare  the  process  of  producing 
value  with  the  labour-process,  pure  and  simple,  we  find  that 
the  latter  consists  of  the  useful  labour,  the  work,  that  produces 
use-values.  Here  we  contemplate  the  labour  as  producing  a 
particular  article  ;  we  view  it  under  its  qualitative  aspect  alone, 
with  regard  to  its  end  and  aim.  But  viewed  as  a  value-creating 
process,  the  same  labour-process  presents  itself  under  its 
quantitative  aspect  alone.  Here  it  is  a  question  merely  of  the 
time  occupied  by  the  labourer  in  doing  the  work;  of  the  period 
during  which  the  labour-power  is  usefully  expended.  Here, 
the  commodities  that  take  part  in  the  process,  do  not  count 
any  longer  as  necessary  adjuncts  of  labour-power  in  the  pro- 
duction of  a  definite,  useful  object.  They  count  merely  as 
depositaries  of  so  much  absorbed  or  materialised  labour ;  that 
labour,  whether  previously  embodied  in  the  means  of  production, 
or  incorporated  in  them  for  the  first  time  during  the  process 
by  the  action  of  labour-power,  counts  in  either  case  only 
according  to  its  duration ;  it  amounts  to  so  many  hours  or  days 
as  the  ca'^e  may  be. 

Moreover,  only  so  much  of  the  time  spent  in  the  production 
of  any  article  is  counted,  as,  under  the  given  social  conditions, 
is  necessary.  The  consequences  of  this  are  various.  In  the 
first  place,  it  becomes  necessary  that  the  labour  should  be 
carried  on  under  normal  conditions.  If  a  self-acting  mule  is 
the  implement  in  general  use  for  spinning,  it  would  be  absurd 
to  supply  the  spinner  with  a  distaff*  and  spinning  wheel.  The 
cotton  too  must  not  be  such  rubbish  as  to  cause  extra  waste  in 
being  worked,  but  must  be  of  suitable  quality.  Otherwise  the 
spinner  would  be  found  to  spend  more  time  in  producing  a 
pound  of  yarn  than  is  socially  necessary,  in  which  case  the 
excess  of  time  would  create  neither  value  nor  money.  But 
whether  the  material  factors  of  the  process  are  of  normal 
qupclity  or  not,  depends  not  upon  the  labourer,  but  entirely  upon 
the  capitalist.  Then  again,  the  labour-power  itself  must  be  of 
average  efficacy.     In  the  trade  in  which  it  is  being  employed, 

M 


178  Capitalist  Prodttction. 

it  must  possess  tlio  average  skill,  handiness  and  quickness  j)re- 
valent  in  that  trade,  and  our  capitalist  took  good  care  to  buy 
labour-power  of  such  normal  goodness.  This  power  must  be 
applied  with  the  average  amount  of  exertion  and  with  the 
usual  degree  of  intensity ;  and  the  capitalist  is  as  careful  to 
see  that  this  is  done,  as  that  his  workmen  are  not  idle  for  a 
single  moment.  He  has  bought  the  use  of  the  labour- power 
for  a  definite  period,  and  he  insists  upon  his  rights.  He  has 
no  intention  of  being  robbed.  Lastly,  and  for  this  purpose  our 
friend  has  a  penal  code  of  his  own,  all  wasteful  consumption  of 
raw  material  or  instruments  of  labour  is  strictly  forbidden,  be- 
cause what  is  so  wasted,  represents  labour  superfluously  ex- 
pended, labour  that  does  not  count  in  the  product  or  enter  into 
its  value.^ 

We  now  see,  that  the  difference  between  labour,  considered 
on  the  one  hand  as  producing  utilities,  and  on  the  other  hand, 

1  This  is  one  of  the  circumstances  that  makes  production  by  slave  labour  such  a 
costly  process.  The  labourer  here  is,  to  use  a  striking  expression  of  the  ancients,  dis- 
tinguishable only  as  instrumentum  vocale,  from  an  animal  as  instrumenfcum  semi- 
vocale,  and  from  an  implement  as  instrumentum  mutum.  But  he  himself  takes  care 
to  let  both  beast  and  implement  feel  that  he  is  none  of  them,  but  is  a  man.  He  con- 
vinces himself  with  immense  satisfaction,  that  he  is  a  different  being,  by  treating 
the  one  unmercifully  and  damaging  the  other  con  amore.  Hence  the  principle,  uni- 
versally applied  in  this  method  of  production,  only  to  employ  the  rudest  and  heaviest 
implements  and  such  as  are  difficult  to  damage  owing  to  their  sheer  clumsiness.  In 
the  slave-states  bordering  on  the  Gulf  of  Mexico,  down  to  the  date  of  the  civil  war, 
ploughs  constructed  on  old  Chinese  models,  which  turned  up  the  soil  like  a  hog  or  a 
mole,  instead  of  making  furrows,  were  alone  to  be  found.  Conf.  J.  C.  Cairns. 
••The  Slave  Power,"  London,  1862,  p.  46-49.  In  his  "Sea  Board  Slave  States," 
Olmsted  tells  us  :  "I  am  here  shown  tools  that  no  man  in  his  senses,  with  us,  would 
allow  a  labourer,  for  whom  he  was  paying  wages,  to  be  encumbered  with  ;  and  the 
excessive  weight  and  clumsiness  of  which,  I  would  judge,  would  make  work  at  least 
ten  per  cent  greater  than  with  those  ordinarily  used  with  us.  And  I  am  assured  that, 
in  the  careless  and  clumsy  way  they  must  be  used  by  the  slaves,  anything  lighter  or 
less  rude  could  not  be  furnished  them  with  good  economy,  and  that  such  tools  as  we 
constantly  give  our  labourers  and  find  our  profit  in  giving  them,  would  not  last  out  a 
day  in  a  Virginia  cornfield— much  lighter  and  more  free  from  stones  though  it  be 
than  ours.  So,  too,  when  I  ask  why  mules  are  so  universally  substituted  for  horses 
on  the  farm,  the  first  reason  given,  and  confessedly  the  most  conclusive  one,  is  that 
horses  cannot  bear  the  treatment  that  they  always  must  get  from  negroes  ;  horses  are 
always  soon  foundered  or  crippled  by  them,  while  mules  will  bear  cudgelling,  or  lose 
a  meal  or  two  now  and  then,  and  not  be  materially  injured,  and  they  do  not  take  cold  or 
get  sick,  if  neglected  or  overworked.  But  I  do  not  need  to  go  further  than  to  the 
window  of  the  room  in  which  I  am  writing,  to  see  at  almost  any  time,  treatment  of 
cattle  that  would  ensure  the  immediate  discharge  of  the  driver  by  almost  any  farmer 
owring  them  in  the  North." 


The  Labour  Process,  179 

as  creating  value,  a  difference  which  we  discovered  by  our 
analysis  of  a  commodity,  resolves  itself  into  a  distinction  be- 
tween two  aspects  of  the  process  of  production. 

The  process  of  production,  considered  on  the  one  hand  as 
the  unity  of  the  labour-process  and  the  process  of  creating 
value,  is  production  of  commodities ;  considered  on  the  other 
hand  as  the  unity  of  the  labour-process  and  the  process  of  pro- 
ducing surplus-value,  it  is  the  capitalist  process  of  production, 
or  capitalist  production  of  com  modities. 

We  stated,  on  a  previous  page,  that  in  the  creation  of  surjdus- 
value  it  does  not  in  the  least  matter,  whether  the  labour  ap- 
propriated by  the  capitalist  be  simple  unskilled  labour  of 
average  quality  or  more  complicated  skilled  labour.  All  labour 
of  a  higher  or  more  complicated  character  than  average  labour 
is  expenditure  of  labour-power  of  a  more  costly  kind,  labour- 
power  whose  production  has  cost  more  time  and  labour,  and 
which  therefore  has  a  higher  value,  than  unskilled  or  simple 
labour-power.  This  power  being  of  higher  value,  its  consump- 
tion is  labour  of  a  higher  class,  labour  that  creates  in  equal  times 
proportionally  higher  values  than  unskilled  labour  does. 
Whatever  difference  in  skill  there  may  be  between  the  labour 
of  a  si)inner  and  that  of  a  jeweller,  the  portion  of  his  labour 
by  which  the  jeweller  merely  replaces  the  value  of  his  own 
labour-power,  does  not  in  any  way  difier  in  quality  from  the 
additional  portion  by  which  he  creates  surplus-value.  In  the 
making  of  jewellery,  just  as  in  spinning,  the  surplus-value  re- 
sults only  from  a  quantitative  excess  of  labour,  from  a  lengthen- 
irig-out  of  one  and  the  same  labour-process,  in  the  one  case,  of 
the  process  of  making  jewels,  in  the  other  of  the  process  of 
making  yarn.^ 

1  The  distinction  between  skilled  and  unskilled  labour  rests  in  part  on  pure  illu- 
sion, or,  to  say  the  least,  on  distinctions  that  have  long  since  ceased  to  be  real,  and 
that  survive  only  by  virtue  of  a  traditional  convention  ;  in  part  on  the  helpless  con- 
dition of  some  groups  of  the  working-class,  a  condition  that  prevents  them  from 
exacting  equally  with  the  rest  the  value  of  their  labour-power.  Accidental  cir- 
cumstances here  play  so  great  a  part,  that  these  two  forms  of  laboiu*  sometimes 
change  places.  Where,  for  instance,  the  physique  of  the  working-class  has  deterio- 
rated, and  is,  relatively  speaking,  exhausted,  which  is  the  case  in  all  countries  with  a 
well  develoijed  capitalist  production,  the  lower  forms  of  labour,  which  demand  great 
expenditure  of  muscle,  are  in  general  considered  as  skilled,  compared  with  much 
more  delicate  forms  of  labour  ;  the  latter  sink  down  to  the  level  of  unskilled  labour 


i8o  '  Capitalist  Pivdudion, 

But  on  the  other  hand,  in  every  process  of  creating  value, 
the  reduction  of  skilled  labour  to  average  social  labour,  e.^., 
one  day  of  skilled  to  six  days  of  unskilled  labour,  is  un- 
avoidable.^ We  therefore  save  ourselves  a  superfluous  opera- 
tion, and  simplify  our  analysis,  by  the  assumption,  that  the 
labour  of  the  workman  employed  by  the  capitalist  is  unskilled 
average  labour. 


CHAPTER  YIIL 

CONSTANT  CAPITAL  AND  VARIABLE  CAPITAL. 

The  various  factors  of  the  labour-process  play  different  parts 
in  forming  the  value  of  the  product. 

The  labourer  adds  fresh  value  to  the  subject  of  his  labour 
by  expending  upon  it  a  given  amount  of  additional  labour,  no 
matter  what,  the  specific  character  and  utility  of  that  labour 
may  be.  On  the  other  hand,  the  values  of  the  means  of  pro- 
duction used  up  in  the  process  are  preserved,  and  present 
themselves  afresh  as  constituent  parts  of  the  value  of  the  pro- 
Take  as  an  example  the  labour  of  a  bricklayer,  winch  in  England  occupies  a  much 
higher  level  than  that  of  a  damask-weaver.  Again,  although  the  labour  of  a  fustian 
cutter  demands  great  bodily  exertion,  and  is  at  the  same  time  unhealthy,  yet  it 
counts  only  as  unskilled  labour.  And  then,  we  must  not  forget,  that  the  so-called 
skilled  labour  does  not  occupy  a  large  space  in  the  field  of  national  labour.  Laing 
estimates  that  in  England  (and  Wales)  the  livelihood  of  11,300,000  people  de]iends 
on  unskilled  labour.  If  from  the  total  population  of  18,000,000  living  at  the  time 
when  he  wrote,  we  deduct  1,000,000  for  the  "genteel  population,"  and  1,500,000 
for  paupers,  vagrants,  criminals,  prostitutes,  &c.,  and  4,650,000  who  compose  the 
middle-elasSj  there  remain  the  above  mentioned  11,000,000.  But  in  his  middle-class 
he  includes  people  that  live  on  the  interest  of  small  investments,  officials,  men  of 
letters,  artists,  schoolmasters  and  the  like,  and  in  order  to  swell  the  number  he  also 
includes  in  these  4,650,000  the  better  paid  portion  of  the  factory  operatives  !  The 
bricklayers,  too,  figure  amongst  them.  (S.  Laing :  "  National  Distress,"  &c.,  London, 
1844.)  "  The  great  class  who  have  nothing  to  give  for  food  but  ordinary  labour,  are 
the  great  bulk  of  the  people."  (James  Mill,  in  art :  "  Colony,"  Supplement  to  the 
Eucyclop.  Brit.,  1831.) 

1  "  Wiiere  reference  is  made  to  labour  as  a  measure  of  value,  it  necessarily  implies 
labour  of  one  particular  kind  .  .  .  the  proportion  which  the  other  kinds  bear  to  it 
being  easily  ascertained."    (  "  Outlines  of  Pol.  Econ.,"  Lond.,  1832,  pp.  22  and  23.) 


Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital.  i8i 

duct ;  the  values  of  the  cotton  and  the  spindle,  for  instance,  re- 
appear again  in  the  value  of  the  yarn.  The  value  of  the 
means  of  production  is  therefore  preserved,  by  being  trans- 
ferred to  the  product.  This  transfer  takes  place  during  the 
conversion  of  those  means  into  a  product,  or  in  other  words, 
during  the  labour-process.  It  is  brought  about  by  labour ;  but 
how? 

The  labourer  does  not  perform  two  operations  at  onco,  one 
in  order  to  add  value  to  the  cotton,  the  other  in  order  to  pre- 
serve the  value  of  the  means  of  production,  or,  what  amounts 
to  the  same  thing,  to  transfer  to  the  yarn,  to  the  product,  the 
value  of  the  cotton  on  which  he  works,  and  part  of  the  value 
of  the  spindle  with  which  he  works.  But,  by  the  very  act  of 
adding  new  value,  he  preserves  their  former  values.  Since, 
however,  the  addition  of  new  value  to  the  subject  of  his  labour, 
and  the  preservation  of  its  former  value,  are  two  entirely  dis- 
tinct results,  produced  simultaneously  by  the  labourer,  during 
one  operation,  it  is  plain  that  this  twofold  nature  of  the 
result  can  be  explained  only  by  the  twofold  nature  of  his 
labour ;  at  one  and  the  same  time,  it  must  in  one  character 
create  value,  and  in  another  character  preserve  or  transfer 
value. 

Now,  in  what  manner  does  every  labourer  add  new  labour 
and  consequently  new  value  ?  Evidently,  only  by  labouring 
productively  in  a  particular  way ;  the  spinner  by  spinning,  the 
weaver  by  weaving,  the  smith  by  forging.  But,  while  thus 
incorporating  labour  generally,  that  is  value,  it  is  by  the  par- 
ticular form  alone  of  the  labour,  by  the  spinning,  the  weaving 
and  the  forging  respectively,  that  the  means  of  production,  the 
cotton  and  spindle,  the  yarn  and  loom,  and  the  iron  and  anvil 
become  constituent  elements  of  the  product,  of  a  new  use- 
value.^  Each  use-value  disappears,  but  only  to  re-appear  under 
a  new  form  in  a  new  use- value.  Now,  we  saw,  when  we  were 
considering  the  process  of  creating  value,  that,  if  a  use-value 
be  effectively  consumed  in  the  production  of  a  new  use-value, 
the  quantity  of  labour  expended  in  the  production  of  the  con- 

1  "  Labour  gives  a  new  creation  for  one  extinguished."     ( "  An  essay  on  the  Polit, 
Econ.  of  Nations,"  London,  1821,  p.  13.) 


1 82  Capitalist  Product  ion. 

sumed  article,  forms  a  portion  of  the  quantity  of  labour 
necessary  to  produce  the  new  use-value ;  this  portion  is  there- 
fore labour  transferred  from  the  means  of  production  to  the 
new  product.  Hence,  the  labourer  preserves  the  values  of  the 
consumed  means  of  production,  or  transfers  them  as  portions  of 
its  value  to  the  product,  not  by  virtue  of  his  additional  labour, 
abstractedly  considered,  but  by  virtue  of  the  particular  useful 
character  of  that  labour,  by  virtue  of  its  special  productive 
form.  In  so  far  then  as  labour  is  such  specific  productive  activ- 
ity, in  so  far  as  it  is  spinning,  weaving,  or  forging,  it  raises,  by 
mere  contact,  the  means  of  production  from  the  dead,  makes 
them  living  factors  of  the  labour-process,  and  combines  with 
them  to  form  the  new  products. 

]f  the  special  productive  labour  of  the  workman  were  not 
spinning,  he  could  not  convert  the  cotton  into  yarn,  and  there- 
fore could  not  transfer  the  values  of  the  cotton  and  spindle  to 
the  yarn.  Suppase  the  same  workman  were  to  change  his 
occupation  to  that  of  a  joiner,  he  would  still  by  a  day's  labour 
add  value  to  the  material  be  works  upon.  Consequently,  we 
see,  first,  that  the  addition  of  new  value  takes  place  not  by 
virtue  of  his  labour  being  spinning  in  particular,  or  joinering 
in  particular,  but  because  it  is  labour  in  the  abstract,  a  portion 
of  the  total  labour  of  society;  and  we  see  next,  that  the  value 
added  is  of  a  given  definite  amount,  not  because  his  labour 
has  a  special  utility,  but  because  it  is  exerted  for  a  definite 
time.  On  the  one  hand,  then,  it  is  by  virtue  of  its  general 
character,  as  being  expenditure  of  human  labour-power  in  the 
abstract,  that  spinning  adds  new  value  to  the  values  of  the 
cotton  and  the  spindle ;  and  on  the  other  hand,  it  is  by  virtue 
of  its  special  character,  as  being  a  concrete,  useful  process,  that 
the  same  labour  of  spinning  both  transfers  the  values  of  the 
means  of  production  to  the  product,  and  preserves  them  in  the 
product.  Hence  at  one  and  the  same  time  there  is  produced  a 
twofold  result. 

By  the  simple  addition  of  a  certain  quantity  of  labour, 
new  value  is  added,  and  by  the  quality  of  this  added 
labour,  the  original  values  of  the  means  of  production 
are  preserved  in  the  pi*oduct.      This  twofold  effect,  resulting 


Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital,  183 

fi'ora  the  twofold  character  of  labour,  may  be  traced  in  various 
phenomena. 

Let  us  assume,  that  some  invention  enables  the  spinner  to 
spin  as  much  cotton  in  6  hours  as  he  was  able  to  spin  before  in 
36  hours.  His  labour  is  now  six  times  as  effective  as  it 
was,  for  the  purposes  of  useful  production.  The  product  of  6 
hours'  work  has  increased  sixfold,  from  6  lbs,  to  36  lbs.  But  now 
the  36  lbs,  of  cotton  absorb  only  the  same  amount  of  labour  as 
formerly  did  the  6  lbs.  One-sixth  as  much  new  labour  isabsorbed 
by  each  pound  of  cotton,  and  consequently,  the  value  added  by 
the  labour  to  each  pound  is  only  one-sixth  of  what  it  formerly 
was.  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  product,  in  the  36  lb  =i.  of  yarn, 
the  value  transferred  from  the  cotton  is  six  times  as  great  as 
before.  By  the  6  hours*  spinning,  the  value  of  the  raw 
material  preserved  and  transferred  to  the  product  is  six  times 
as  great  as  before,  although  the  new  value  added  by  the 
labour  of  the  spinner  to  each  pound  of  the  very  same  raw 
material  is  one-sixth  what  it  was  formerlv.  This  shows  that  the 
two  properties  of  labour,  by  virtue  of  which  it  is  enabled  in 
one  case  to  preserve  value,  and  in  the  other  to  create  value,  are 
essentially  different.  On  the  one  hand,  the  longer  the  time 
necessary  to  spin  a  given  weight  of  cotton  into  yarn,  the 
greater  is  the  n&w  value  added  to  the  material ;  on  the  other 
hand,  the  greater  the  weight  of  the  cotton  spun  in  a  given  time, 
the  greater  is  the  value  preserved,  by  being  transferred  from  it 
to  the  product. 

Let  us  now  assume,  that  the  productiveness  of  the  spinner's 
labour,  instead  of  varying,  remains  constant,  that  he  therefore 
requires  the  same  time  as  he  formerly  did,  to  convert  one 
pound  of  cotton  into  yarn,  but  that  the  exchange  value  of  the 
cotton  varies,  either  by  rising  to  six  times  its  former  value  or  fall- 
ing to  one-sixth  of  that  value.  In  both  these  cases,  the  spinner 
puts  the  same  quantity  of  labour  into  a  pound  of  cotton,  and 
therefore  adds  as  much  value,  as  he  did  before  the  change  in 
the  value :  he  also  produces  a  given  weight  of  yarn  in  the 
same  time  as  he  did  before.  Nevertheless,  the  value  that  he 
transfers  from  the  cotton  to  the  yarn  is  either  one-sixth  of  what 
it  was  before  the  variation,  or,  as  the  case  maybe,  six  times  as 


1 84  Capitalist  Production, 

much  as  before.  The  same  result  occurs  when  the  value  of  the 
instruments  of  labour  rises  or  falls,  while  their  useful  efficacy 
in  the  process  remains  unaltered. 

Again,  if  the  technical  conditions  of  the  spinning  process  re- 
main unchanged,  and  no  change  of  value  takes  place  in  the 
means  of  production,  the  spinner  continues  to  consume  in 
equal  working-times  equal  quantities  of  raw  material,  and  equal 
quantities  of  machinery  of  unvarying  value.  The  value  that 
he  preserves  in  the  product  is  directly  proportional  to  the  new 
value  that  he  adds  to  the  product.  In  two  weeks  he  incor- 
porates twice  as  much  labour,  and  therefore  twice  as  much 
value,  as  in  one  week,  and  during  the  same  time  he  consumes 
twice  as  much  material,  and  wears  out  twice  as  much 
machinery,  of  double  the  value  in  each  case  ;  he  therefore  pre- 
serves, in  the  product  of  two  weeks,  twice  as  much  value  as  in 
the  product  of  one  week.  So  long  as  the  conditions  of  produc- 
tion remain  the  same,  the  more  value  the  labourer  adds  by 
fresh  labour,  the  more  value  he  transfers  and  preserves  ;  but  he 
does  so  merely  because  this  addition  of  new  value  takes  place 
under  conditions  that  have  not  varied  and  are  independent  of 
his  own  labour.  Of  course,  it  may  be  said  in  one  sense,  that 
the  labourer  preserves  old  value  always  in  proportion  to  the 
quantity  of  new  value  -/ijat  he  adds.  Whether  the  value  of 
cotton  rise  from  one  shillinor  to  two  shillinsfs,  or  fall  to  six- 
pence,  the  workman  invariably  preserves  in  the  product  of  one 
hour  only  one  half  as  much  value  as  he  preserves  in  two  hours. 
In  like  manner,  if  the  productiveness  of  his  own  labour  varies 
by  rising  or  falling,  he  will  in  one  hour  spin  either  more  or  less 
cotton,  as  the  case  may  be,  than  he  did  before,  and  will  con- 
sequently preserve  in  the  product  of  one  hour,  more  or  less 
value  of  cotton ;  but,  all  the  same,  he  will  preserve  b}'  two 
hours'  labour  twice  as  much  value  as  he  will  by  one. 

Value  exists  only  in  articles  of  utility,  in  objects :  we  leave 
out  of  consideration  its  purely  symbolical  representation  by 
tokens.  (Man  himself,  viewed  as  the  impersonation  of  labour- 
power,  is  a  natural  object,  a  thing,  although  a  living  conscious 
thing,  and  labour  is  the  manifestation  of  this  power  residing  in 
him.)     If  therefore  an  article  loses  its  utility,  it  also  loses  its 


Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital.  185 

value.  The  reason  why  means  of  production  do  not  lose  their 
value,  at  the  same  time  that  they  lose  their  use-value,  is  this  : 
they  lose  in  the  labour-process  the  original  form  of  their  use- 
value,  only  to  assume  in  the  product  the  form  of  a  new  use-value. 
But,  however  important  it  may  be  to  value,  that  it  should  have 
some  object  of  utility  to  embody  itself  in,  yet  it  is  a  matter  of 
complete  indifference  what  particular  object  serves  this  purpose  j 
this  we  saw  when  treating  of  the  metamorphosis  of  commodities. 
Hence  it  follows  that  in  the  labour-process  the  means  of  pro- 
duction transfer  their  value  to  the  product  only  so  far  as  along 
with  their  use-value  they  lose  also  their  exchange  value. 
They  give  up  to  the  product  that  value  alone  which  they 
themselves  lose  as  means  of  production.  But  in  this  respect  the 
material  factors  of  the  labour-process  do  not  all  behave  alike. 

The  coal  burnt  under  the  boiler  vanishes  without  leaving  a 
trace ;  so,  too,  the  tallow  with  which  the  axles  of  wheels  are 
greased.  Dye  stuffs  and  other  auxiliary  substances  also  vanish 
but  re-appear  as  properties  of  the  product.  Raw  material 
forms  the  substance  of  the  product,  but  only  after  it  has  chajiged 
its  form.  Hence  raw  material  and  auxiliary  substances  lose 
the  characteristic  form  with  which  they  are  clothed  on  entering 
the  labour-process.  It  is  otherwise  with  the  instruments  of 
labour.  Tools,  machines,  workshops,  and  vessels,  are  of  use  in 
the  labour-process,  only  so  long  as  they  retain  their  original 
shape,  and  are  ready  each  morning  to  renew  the  process  with 
their  shape  unchanged.  And  just  as  during  their  lifetime, 
that  is  to  say,  during  the  continued  labour-process  in  which 
they  serve,  they  retain  their  shape  independent  of  the  product, 
so,  too,  they  do  after  their  death.  The  corpses  of  machines, 
tools,  workshops,  &;c.,  are  always  separate  and  distinct  from  the 
product  they  helped  to  turn  out.  If  we  now  consider  the  case 
of  any  instrument  of  labour  during  the  whole  period  of  its 
service,  from  the  day  of  its  entry  into  the  workshop,  till  the 
day  of  its  banishment  into  the  lumber  room,  we  find  that  dur- 
ing this  period  its  use-value  has  been  completely  consumed, 
and  therefore  its  exchange  value  completely  transferred  to  the 
product.  For  instance,  if  a  spinning  machine  lasts  for  10  years, 
it  is  plain  that  during  that  working  period  its  total  value  is 


1 86  Capitalist  Production. 

gradually  transferred  to  the  product  of  the  10  years.  The  life- 
time of  an  instrument  of  labour,  therefore,  is  spent  in  the 
repetition  of  a  greater  or  less  number  of  similar  operations. 
Its  life  may  be  compared  with  that  of  a  human  being.  Every 
day  brings  a  man  24  hours  nearer  to  his  grave :  but  how  many 
days  he  has  still  to  travel  on  that  road,  no  man  can  tell 
accurately  by  merely  looking  at  him.  This  difficulty,  however, 
does  not  prevent  life  insurance  offices  from  drawing,  by  means 
of  the  theory  of  averages,  very  accurate,  and  at  the  same  time 
very  profitable  conclusions.  So  it  is  with  the  instruments  of 
labour.  It  is  known  by  experience  how  long  on  the  average  a 
machine  of  a  particular  kind  will  last.  Suppose  its  use- value 
in  the  labour-process  to  last  only  six  days.  Then,  on  the 
average,  it  loses  each  day  one-sixth  of  its  use- value,  and  there- 
fore parts  with  one-sixth  of  its  value  to  the  daily  product.  The 
wear  and  tear  of  all  instruments,  their  daily  loss  of  use-value, 
and  the  corresponding  quantity  of  value  they  part  with  to  the 
product,  are  accordingly  calculated  upon  this  basis. 

It  is  thus  strikingly  clear,  that  means  of  production  never 
transfer  more  value  to  the  product  than  they  themselves  lose 
during  the  labour-process  by  the  destruction  of  their  own  use- 
value.  If  such  an  instrument  has  no  value  to  lose,  if,  in  other 
words,  it  is  not  the  product  of  human  labour,  it  transfers  no 
value  to  the  product.  It  helps  to  create  use- value  without  con- 
tributing to  the  formation  of  exchange  value.  In  this  class  are 
included  all  means  of  production  supplied  by  Nature  without 
human  assistance,  such  as  land,  wind,  water,  metals  in  situ,  and 
timber  in  virgin  forests. 

Yet  another  interesting  phenomenon  here  presents  itself. 
Suppose  a  machine  to  be  worth  £1000,  and  to  wear  out  in  1000 
days.  Then  one  thousandth  part  of  the  value  of  the  machine 
is  daily  transferred  to  the  day's  product.  At  the  same  time, 
though  with  diminishing  vitality,  the  machine  as  a  whole  con- 
tinues to  take  part  in  the  labour-process.  Thus  it  appears, 
that  one  factor  of  the  labour-process,  a  means  of  production, 
continually  enters  as  a  w^hole  into  that  process,  while  it  enters 
into  the  process  of  the  formation  of  value  by  fractions  only. 
The  difference  between  the  two  processes  is  here  reflected  in 


Constmit  Capital  and  Variable  Capital,  187 

their  material  factors,  by  the  same  instrument  of  production 
taking  part  as  a  whole  in  the  labour-process,  while  at  the  same 
time  as  an  element  in  the  formation  of  value,  it  enters  only  by 
fractions/ 

On  the  other  hand,  a  means  of  production  may  take  part  as  a 
whole  in  the  formation  of  value,  while  into  the  labour-process 
it  enters  only  bit  by  bit.  Suppose  that  in  spinning  cotton,  the 
waste  for  every  115  lbs.  used  amounts  to  15  lbs.,  which  is  con- 
verted, not  into  yarn,  but  into  "  devil's  dust."  Now,  although 
this  15  lbs.  of  cotton  never  becomes  a  constituent  element  of 
the  yarn,  yet  assuming  this  amount  of  waste  to  be  normal  and 
inevitable  under  average  conditions  of  spinning,  its  value  is 
just  as  surely  transferred  to  the  value  of  the  yarn,  as  is  the 
value  of  the  100  lbs.  that  form  the  substance  of  the  yarn.  The 
use-value  of  15  lbs.  of  cotton  must  vanish  into  dust,  before  100 
lbs.  of  yarn  can  be  made.  The  destruction  of  this  cotton  is 
therefore  a  necessary  condition  in  the  production  of  the  yarn. 
And  because  it  is  a  necessary  condition,  and  for  no  other  reason^ 
the  value  of  that  cotton  is  transferred  to  the  product.  The  same 
holds  good  for  every  kind  of  refuse  resulting  from  a  labour- 
process,  so  far  at  least  as  such  refuse  cannot  be  further  employed 
as  a  means  in  the  production  of  new  and  independent  use-values- 

1  The  subject  of  repairs  of  the  implements  of  labour  does  not  concern  us  here.  A 
machine  that  is  undergoing  repair,  no  longer  plays  the  part  of  an  instrument,  but 
that  of  a  subject  of  labour.  Work  is  no  longer  done  with  it,  but  upon  it.  It  is  quite 
permissible  for  our  purpose  to  assume,  that  the  labour  expended  on  the  repairs  of  in- 
struments is  included  in  the  labour  necessary  for  their  original  production.  But  in 
the  text  we  deal  with  that  wear  and  tear,  which  no  doctor  can  cure,  and  which  little 
by  little  brings  about  death,  with  *'  that  kind  of  wear  which  cannot  be  repaired  from 
time  to  time,  and  which,  in  the  case  of  a  knife,  would  ultimately  reduce  it  to  a  state 
in  which  the  cutler  would  say  of  it,  it  is  not  worth  a  new  blade."  We  have  shewn  in 
the  text,  that  a  machine  takes  part  in  every  labour-process  as  an  integral  machine,  but 
that  into  the  simultaneous  process  of  creating  value  it  enters  only  bit  by  bit.  How 
great  then  is  the  confusion  of  ideas  exhibited  in  the  following  extract !  "  Mr.  Ricardo 
says  a  i^ortion  of  the  labour  of  the  engineer  in  making  [stocking]  machines  "  is 
contained  for  example  in  the  value  of  a  pair  of  stockings.  "  Yet  the  total  labour, 
that  produced  each  single  pair  of  stockings  ....  includes  the  whole  labour  of 
the  engineer,  not  a  portion  ;  for  one  machine  makes  many  pairs,  and  none  of  those 
pairs  could  have  been  done  without  any  part  of  the  machine."  ("  Obs.  on  certain  verbal 
disputesinPol.Econ.  particularly  relating  to  value,"p.  54.)  The  author,  an  uncommonly 
self-satisfied  wiseacre,  is  right  in  his  confusion  and  therefore  in  his  contention,  to  this 
extent  only  that  neither  Ricardo  nor  any  other  economist,  before  or  since  him,  has 
accurately  distinguished  the  two  aspects  of  labour,  and  still  less,  therefore,  the  part 
played  by  it  under  each  of  these  aspects  in  the  formation  of  value. 


1 88  Capitalist  Production. 

Such  an  employment  of  refuse  may  be  seen  in  the  large  machine 
works  at  Manchester,  where  mountains  of  iron  turnings  are 
carted  away  to  the  foundry  in  the  evening,  in  order  the  next 
morning  to  re-appear  in  the  workshops  as  solid  masses  of 
iron. 

We  have  seen  that  the  means  of  production  transfer  value  to 
the  new  product,  so  far  only  as  during  the  labour-process  they 
lose  value  in  the  shape  of  their  old  use- value.  The  maximum 
loss  of  value  that  they  can  suffer  in  the  process,  is  plainly 
limited  by  the  amount  of  the  original  value  with  whicli  they 
came  into  the  process,  or  in  other  words,  by  the  labour-time 
necessary  for  their  production.  Therefore,  the  means  of  pro- 
duction can  never  add  more  value  to  the  product  than  they 
themselves  possess  independently  of  the  process  in  which  they 
assist.  However  useful  a  given  kind  of  raw  material,  or  a 
machine,  or  other  means  of  production  may  be,  though  it  may 
cost  £150,  or,  say,  500  days'  labour,  yet  it  cannot,  under  any 
circumstances,  add  to  the  value  of  the  product  more  than  £150. 
Its  value  is  determined  not  by  the  labour-process  into  which  it 
enters  as  a  means  of  production,  but  by  that  out  of  which  it  has 
issued  as  a  product.  \\i  the  labour-process  it  only  serves  as  a 
mere  use-value,  a  thing  with  useful  properties,  and  could  not, 
therefore,  transfer  an}^  value  to  the  product,  unless  it  possessed 
such  value  previously.^ 

1  From  this  we  may  judge  of  tlie  absurdity  of  J.  B.  Say,  who  pretends  to  account 
for  surplus-value  (Interest,  Profit,  Rent),  by  the  "services  productifs  "  which  the 
means  of  production,  soil,  instruments,  and  raw  material,  render  in  the  labour-process 
by  means  of  their  use-values.  Mr.  Wra.  Roscher  who  seldom  loses  an  occasion  of  re- 
gistering, in  black  and  white,  ingenious  apologetic  fancies,  records  the  following 
specimen :— "  J.  B.  Say  (Traits,  t.  1.  ch.  4)  very  truly  remarks :  the  value  produced 
by  an  oil  mill,  aftar  deduction  of  all  costs,  is  something  new,  something  quite  different 
from  the  labour  by  which  the  oil  mill  itself  was  erected."  (1.  c,  p.  82,  note.)  Very 
true,  Mr.  Professor  !  the  oil  produced  by  the  oil  mill  is  iudeed  something  very  different 
from  the  labour  expended  in  constructing  the  mill !  By  value,  Mr  Roscher  under- 
stands such  stuff  as  "  oil,"  because  oil  has  value,  notwithstanding  that  "  Nature  "  pro- 
duces petroleum,  though  relatively  "  in  small  quantities,"  a  fact  to  which  he  seems  to 
refer  in  his  further  observation  :  "  It  (Nature)  produces  scarcely  any  exchange-value." 
Mr.  Roscher's  "Nature"  and  the  exchange-value  it  produces  are  rather  like  the 
foolish  virgin  who  admitted  indeed  that  she  had  had  a  child,  but  "  it  was  such  a  little 
one."  This  "savant  serieux"  in  continuation  remarks :  "  Ricardo's  school  is  in  the 
habit  of  including  capital  as  accumulated  labour  under  the  head  of  labour.  This  is 
unskilful  work,  because,  indeed,  the  owner  of  capital,  after  all,  does  something  more 
than  the  merely  creating  and  preserving  of  the  same :  namely,  the  abstention  from 


Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital.  1 89 

While  productive  labour  is  changing  the  means  of  produc- 
tion into  constituent  elements  of  a  new  product,  their  value 
undergoes  a  metempsychosis.  Tt  deserts  the  consumed  body, 
to  occupy  the  new^ly  created  one.  But  this  transmigration 
takes  place,  as  it  were,  behind  the  back  of  the  labourer.  He 
is  unable  to  add  new  labour,  to  create  new  value,  without  a 
the  same  time  preserving  old  values,  and  this,  because  th 
labour  he  adds  must  be  of  a  specific  useful  kind  ;  and  he  can- 
not do  work  of  a  useful  kind,  without  employing  products  as 
the  means  of  production  of  a  new  product,  and  thereby  trans- 
ferring their  value  to  the  new  product.  The  property  there- 
fore which  labour- power  in  action,  living  labour,  possesses  of 
preserving  value,  at  the  same  time  that  it  adds  it,  is  a  gift  of 
Nature  which  costs  the  labourer  nothing,  but  which  is  very 
advantageous  to  the  capitalist  inasmuch  as  it  preserves  the 
existing  value  of  his  capital.^  So  long  as  trade  is  good,  the 
capitalist  is  too  much  absorbed  in  money-grubbing  to  take 
notice  of  this  gratuitous  gift  of  labour.  A  violent  interruption 
of  the  labour-process  by  a  crisis,  makes  him  sensitively  aware 
of  \i? 

As  regards  the  means  of  production,  what  is  really  consumed 
is  their  use- value,  and  the  consumption  of  this  use-value  by  labour 

the  enjoyment  of  it,  for  which  he  demands,  e.gf.,  interest."  (1.  c.)  How  very  "skil- 
ful" is  this  '*  anatomico-physiological method  "of  political  economy,  which,  "indeed," 
converts  a  mere  desire  "  after  all "  into  a  source  of  value. 

1  "Of  all  the  instruments  of  the  farmers'  trade,  the  labour  of  man  ...  is  that  on 
which  he  is  most  to  rely  for  the  repayment  of  his  capital.  The  other  tvvo  .  .  .  the  work- 
ing stock  of  the  cattle  and  the  .  .  .  carts,  ploughs,  spades,  and  so  forth,  without  a 
given  portion  of  the  first,  are  nothing  at  all."  (Edmund  Burke  :  "  Thoughts  and  De- 
tails on  Scarcity,  originally  presented  to  the  Right  Hon.  W.  Pitt,  in  the  month  of 
November  1795,"  Edit.  London,  1800,  p.  10.) 

2  In  "  Tlie  Times  "  of  26th  November,  1862,  a  manufacturer,  whose  mill  employed 
800  hands,  and  consumed,  on  the  average,  150  bales  of  East  Indian,  or  130  bales  of 
American  cotton,  complains,  in  doleful  manner,  of  the  standing  expenses  of  his 
factory  when  not  working.  He  estimates  them  at  £6,000  a  year.  Among  them  are 
a  number  of  items  that  do  not  concern  us  here,  such  as  rent,  rates,  and  taxes,  in- 
surance, salaries  of  the  manager,  book-keeper,  engineer,  and  others.  Then  he  reckons 
£150  for  coal  used  to  heat  the  mill  occasionally,  and  run  the  engine  now  and  then. 
Besides  this,  he  includes  the  wages  of  the  people  employed  at  odd  times  to  keep  the 
machinery  in  working  order.  Lastly,  he  puts  down  £1,200  for  depreciation  of 
machinery,  because  "  the  weather  and  the  natural  principle  of  decay  do  not  suspend 
their  operations  because  the  steam-engine  ceases  to  revolve."  He  says,  emphatically, 
he  does  not  estimate  his  depreciation  at  more  than  the  smaU  sum  of  £1,200,  because 
his  machinery  is  already  nearly  worn  out. 


I  go  Capitalist  Production. 

results  in  the  product.  There  is  no  consumption  of  their  value/ 
and  it  would  therefore  be  inaccurate  to  say  that  it  is  reproduced. 
It  is  rather  preserved  ;  not  by  reason  of  any  0[»eration  it  under- 
goes itself  in  the  process ;  but  because  the  article  in  which  it 
originally  exists,  vanishes,  it  is  true,  but  vanishes  into  some 
other  article.  Hence,  in  the  value  of  the  product,  there  is  a 
re-appearance  of  the  value  of  the  means  of  production,  but 
there  is,  strictly  speaking,  no  reproduction  of  that  value.  That 
which  is  produced  is  a  new  use- value  in  which  the  old  exchange- 
value  re-appears.2 

It  is  otherwise  with  the  subjective  factor  of  the  labour-pro- 
cess, with  labour-power  in  action.  While  the  labourer,  by 
virtue  of  his  labour  being  of  a  specialised  kind  that  has  a 
special  object,  preserves  and  transfers  to  the  product  the  value 
of  the  means  of  production,  he  at  the  same  time,  by  the  mere 
act  of  working,  creates  each  instant  an  additional  or  new  value. 
Suppose  the  process  of  production  to  be  stopped  just  when  the 
workman  has  produced  an  equivalent  for  the  value  of  his  own 
labour-power,  when,  for  example,  by  six  hours'  labour,  he  has 
added  a  value  of  three  shillings.  This  value  is  the  surplus,  of 
the  total  value  of  the  product,  over  the  portion  of  its  value 
that  is  due  t .)  the  means  of  production.  It  is  the  only  original 
bit  of  value  formed  during  this  process,  the  only  yjortion  of  the 
value  of  the  product  created  by  this  process.     Of  course,  we 

1  "Productive  consumption  ...  where  the  consumption  of  a  commodity  is  a  pert  of 
the  process  of  production.  .  .  .  In  these  instances  there  is  no  consumption  of  value." 
(S.  P.  Newman,  1.  c.  p.  293.) 

2  In  an  American  compendium  that  has  gone  through,  perhaps,  20  editions,  this 
imssage  occurs:  "It  matters  not  in  what  form  capital  re-appears;"  then  after  a 
lengthy  enumeration  of  all  the  possible  ingredients  of  production  whose  value  re- 
appears in  the  product,  the  passage  concludes  thus:  "The  various  kinds  of  food, 
clothing,  and  shelter,  necessary  for  the  existence  and  comfort  of  the  human  being, 
are  also  changed.  They  are  consumed  from  time  to  time,  and  their  value  re-appears 
in  that  new  vigour  imparted  to  his  body  and  mind,  forming  fresh  capital,  to  be  em- 
ployed again  in  the  work  of  production."  (F.  Wayland,  1.  c.  pp.  31,  32  )  Without 
noticing  any  other  oddities,  it  suflBces  to  observe,  that  what  re-appears  in  the  fresh 
vigour,  is  not  the  bread's  price,  but  its  blood-forming  substances.  What,  on  the 
other  hand,  re-appears  in  the  value  of  that  vigour,  is  not  the  means  of  subsistence, 
but  their  value.  The  same  necessaries  of  life,  at  half  the  price,  would  form  just  as 
much  muscle  and  bone,  just  as  much  vigour,  but  not  vigour  of  the  same  value.  This 
confusion  of  "  value "  and  "vigour  "  coupled  with  our  author's  pharisaical  indefinite- 
ness,  mark  an  attempt,  futile  for  all  that,  to  thrash  out  an  explanation  of  surplus- 
value  from  a  mere  re-appearance  of  pre-existing  values. 


Constant  Capital  and  Variable  Capital,  1 9 1 

do  not  forget  that  this  new  value  only  replaces  the  money 
advanced  by  the  capitalist  in  the  purchase  of  the  labour-power, 
and  spent  by  the  labourer  on  the  necessaries  of  life.  With 
regard  to  the  money  spent,  the  new  value  is  merely  a  repro- 
duction ;  but,  nevertheless,  it  is  an  actual,  and  not,  as  in  the 
case  of  the  value  of  the  means  of  production,  only  an  apparent, 
reproduction.  The  substitution  of  one  value  for  another,  is 
here  effected  by  the  creation  of  new  value. 

We  know,  however,  from  what  has  gone  before,  that  the 
labour-process  may  continue  beyond  the  time  necessary  to  re- 
produce and  incorporate  in  the  product  a  mere  equivalent  for 
the  value  of  the  labour-power.  Instead  of  the  six  hours  that 
are  sufficient  for  the  latter  purpose,  the  process  may  continue 
for  twelve  hours.  The  action  of  labour-power,  therefore,  not 
only  reproduces  its  own  value,  but  produces  value  over  and 
above  it.  This  surplus-value  is  the  difference  between  the 
value  of  the  product  and  the  value  of  the  elements  consumed 
in  the  formation  of  that  product,  in  other  words,  of  the  means 
of  production  and  the  labour-power. 

By  our  explanation  of  the  different  parts  played  by  the  vari- 
ous factors  of  the  labour-process  in  the  formation  of  the  pro- 
duct's value,  we  have,  in  fact,  disclosed  the  characters  of  the 
different  functions  allotted  to  the  different  elements  of  capital 
in  the  process  of  expanding  its  own  value.  The  surplus  of  the 
total  value  of  the  product,  over  the  sum  of  the  values  of  its 
constituent  factors,  is  the  surplus  of  the  expanded  capital  over 
the  capital  originally  advanced.  The  means  of  production  on 
the  one  hand,  labour-power  on  the  other,  are  merely  the  differ- 
ent modes  of  existence  which  the  value  of  the  original  capital 
assumed  when  from  being  money  it  was  transformed  into  the 
various  factors  of  the  labour-process.  That  part  of  capital 
then,  which  is  represented  by  the  means  of  production,  by  the 
raw  material,  auxiliary  material  and  the  instruments  of  labour, 
does  not,  in  the  process  of  production,  undergo  any  quantitative 
alteration  of  value.  I  therefore  call  it  the  constant  part  of 
capital,  or,  more  shortly,  constant  capital. 

On  the  other  hand,  that  part  of  capital,  represented  by 
labour-power,  does,  in  the  process  of  production,  undergo  an 


r92  Capitalist  Production. 

alteration  of  value.  It  both  reproduces  the  equivalent  of  its; 
own  value,  and  also  produces  an  excess,  a  surplus-value,  which 
may  itself  vary,  may  be  more  or  less  according  to  circumstances. 
This  part  of  capital  is  continually  being  transformed  from  a 
constant  into  a  variable  magnitude.  I  therefore  call  it  the 
variable  part  of  capital,  or,  shortly,  variable  capital.  The  same 
elements  of  capital  which,  from  the  point  of  view  of  the 
labour-process,  present  themselves  respectively  as  the  objective 
and  subjective  factors,  as  means  of  production  and  labour- 
power,  present  themselves,  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  pro- 
cess of  creating  surplus-value,  as  constant  and  variable  capital. 
The  definition  of  constant  capital  given  above  by  no  means 
excludes  the  possibility  of  a  change  of  value  ia  its  elements. 
Sup]30se  the  price  of  cotton  to  be  one  day  sixpence  a  pound, 
and  the  next  day,  in  consequence  of  a  failure  of  the  cotton  crop, 
a  shilling  a  pound.  Each  pound  of  the  cotton  bought  at  six- 
pence, and  worked  up  after  tlie  rise  in  value,  transfers  to  the 
product  a  value  of  one  shilling ;  and  the  cotton  already  spun 
before  the  rise,  and  perhaps  circulating  in  the  market  as  yarn, 
likewise  transfers  to  the  product  twice  its  original  value.  It 
is  plain,  however,  that  these  changes  of  value  are  independent 
of  the  increment  or  surplus-value  added  to  the  value  of  the 
cotton  by  the  spinning  itself.  If  the  old  cotton  had  never 
been  spun,  it  could,  after  the  rise,  be  resold  at  a  shilling  a 
pound  instead  of  at  sixpence.  Further,  the  fewer  the  processes 
the  cotton  has  gone  through,  the  more  certain  is  this  result. 
We  therefore  find  that  speculators  make  it  a  rule  when  such 
sudden  changes  in  value  occur,  to  speculate  in  that  material  on 
which  the  least  possible  quantity  of  labour  has  been  spent :  to 
speculate,  therefore,  in  yarn  rather  than  in  cloth,  in  cotton  it- 
self, rather  than  in  yarn.  The  change  of  value  in  the  case  we 
have  been  considering,  originates,  not  in  the  process  in  which  the 
cotton  plays  the  part  of  a  means  of  production,  and  in  which  it 
therefore  functions  as  constant  capital,  but  in  the  process  in 
which  the  cotton  itself  is  produced.  The  value  of  a  commodity, 
it  is  true,  is  determined  by  the  quantity  of  labour  contained  in 
it,  but  this  quantity  is  itself  limited  by  social  conditions.  If 
the  time  socially  necessary  for  the  production  of   any  com- 


Const a7it  Capital  and  Variable  Capital  193 

modity  alters — and  a  given  weight  of  cotton  represents,  after  a 
bad  harvest,  more  labour  than  after  a  good  one — all  previously 
existing  commodities  of  the  same  class  are  affected,  because  they 
are,  as  it  were,  only  individuals  of  the  species,^  and  their 
value  at  any  given  time  is  measured  by  the  labour  sociall}^ 
necessary,  i.e.,  by  the  labour  necessary  for  their  production 
under  the  then  existinor  social  conditions. 

As  the  value  of  the  raw  material  may  change,  so,  too,  may 
that  of  the  instruments  of  labour,  of  the  machinery,  &c.,  em- 
ployed in  the  process ;  and  consequently  that  portion  of  the 
value  of  the  product  transferred  to  it  from  them,  may  also 
change.  If  in  consequence  of  a  new  invention,  machinery  of  a 
particular  kind  can  be  produced  by  a  diminished  expenditure 
of  labour,  the  old  machinery  becomes  depreciated  more  or  less, 
and  consequently  transfers  so  much  less  value  to  the  product. 
But  here  again,  the  change  in  value  originates  outside  the 
process  in  which  the  machine  is  acting  as  a  means  of  pro- 
duction. Once  engaged  in  this  process,  the  machine  cannot 
transfer  more  value  than  it  possesses  apart  from  the  process. 

Just  as  a  change  in  the  value  of  the  means  of  pro- 
duction, even  after  they  have  commenced  to  take  a  part  in  the 
labour  process,  does  not  alter  their  character  as  constant 
capital,  so,  too,  a  change  in  the  proportion  of  constant  to 
variable  capital  does  not  affect  the  respective  functions  of  these 
two  kinds  of  capital.  The  technical  conditions  of  the  labour 
process  may  be  revolutionised  to  such  an  extent,  that  where 
formerly  ten  men  using  tin  implements  of  small  value  worked 
up  a  relatively  small  quantity  of  raw  material,  one  man  may 
now,  with  the  aid  of  one  expensive  machine,  work  up  one 
hundred  times  as  much  raw  material.  In  the  latter  case  wo 
have  an  enormous  increase  in  the  constant  cai)ital,  that  is  re- 
presented by  the  total  value  of  the  means  of  production  used, 
and  at  the  same  time  a  great  reduction  in  the  variable  ca})ital, 
invested  in  labour-power.  Such  a  revolution,  however,  alters 
only  the  quantitative  relation  between  the  constant  and  the 

1  "Toutes  les  productions  d'un  meme  genre  ne  foment  proprement  qu'une  masse, 
dont  le  prix  se  determine  eu  general  et  sans  egard  aux  circonstauces  particulieres. " 
(Le  Trosne,  1.  c,  p.  803.) 

N 


194  Capitalist  Production, 

variable  capital,  or  the  proportions  in  which  the  total  capital 
is  split  up  into  its  constant  and  variable  constituents  ;  it  has 
not  in  the  least  degree  affected  the  essential  difference  between 
the  two. 


CHAPTER   IX. 

THE  RATE  OF   SURPLUS-VALUE. 

SECTION   1.  — THE   DEGREE   OP  EXPLOITATION   OP  LABOUR-POWER. 

The  surplus- value  generated  in  the  process  of  production  by  C, 
the  capital  advanced,  or  in  other  words,  the  self -expansion  of 
the  value  of  the  capital  C,  presents  itself  for  our  consideration, 
in  the  first  place,  as  a  surplus,  as  the  amount  by  which  the 
value  of  the  product  exceeds  the  value  of  its  constituent 
elements. 

The  capital  C  is  made  up  of  two  components,  one,  the  sum 
of  money  c  laid  out  upon  the  means  of  production,  and  the 
other,  the  sum  of  money  v  expended  upon  the  labour-power ; 
c  represents  the  portion  that  has  become  constant  capital,  and 
V  the  portion  that  has  become  variable  capital.  At  first  then, 
C=c+v:  for  example,  if  £500  is  the  capital  advanced,  its  com- 
ponents may  be  such  that  the  £500=£410  const. +  £90  var. 
When  the  process  of  production  is  finished,  we  get  a  com- 
modity whose  value=(c4-v)  +  s,  where  s  is  the  surplus- value  ; 
or  taking  our  former  figures,  the  value  of  this  commodity  may 
be  (£410  const. -f  £90  var.) +  £90  surpl.  The  original  capital 
has  now  changed  from  C  to  C,  from  £500  to  £590.  The  differ- 
ence is  8  or  a  surplus  value  of  £90.  Since  the  value  of  the 
constituent  elements  of  the  product  is  equal  to  the  value  of 
the  advanced  capital,  it  is  mere  tautology  to  say,  that  the  ex- 
cess of  the  value  of  the  product  over  the  value  of  its  constitu- 
ent elements,  is  equal  to  the  expansion  of  the  capital  advanced 
or  to  the  surplus- value  produced. 

Nevertheless,  we  must  examine  this  tautology  a  little  more 


77/6'  Rate  oj  Stirphts-vahie,  195 

closely.  Tlie  two  things  compared  are,  the  value  of  the  pro- 
duct and  the  value  of  its  constituents  consumed  in  the  process 
of  production.  Now  we  have  seen  how  that  portion  of  the 
constant  capital  which  consists  of  the  instruments  of  labour, 
transfers  to  the  product  only  a  fraction  of  its  value,  while  the 
remainder  of  that  value  continues  to  reside  in  those  instru- 
ments. Since  this  remainder  plays  no  part  in  the  formation  of 
value,  we  may  at  present  leave  it  on  one  side.  To  introduce  it 
into  the  calculation  would  make  no  difference.  For  instance, 
taking  our  former  example,  c=:£410:  suppose  this  sum  to  con- 
sist of  £312  value  of  raw  material,  £44  value  of  auxiliary 
material,  and  £54  value  of  the  machinery  worn  away  in  the 
process;  and  suppose  that  the  total  value  of  the  machinery 
employed  is  £1,054.  Out  of  this  latter  sum,  then,  we  reckon 
as  advanced  for  the  purpose  of  turning  out  the  product,  the 
sum  of  £54  alone,  which  the  machinery  loses  by  wear  and 
tear  in  the  process  ;  for  this  is  all  it  parts  with  to  the  product. 
Now  if  we  also  reckon  the  remaining  £1,000,  which  still  con- 
tinues in  the  machinery,  as  transferred  to  the  product,  we 
ought  also  to  reckon  it  as  part  of  the  value  advanced,  and  thus 
make  it  appear  on  both  sides  of  our  calculation.^  We  should, 
in  this  way,  get  £1,500  on  one  side  and  £1,590  on  the  other. 
The  difference  of  these  two  sums,  or  the  surplus-value,  would 
still  be  £90.  Throughout  this  Book  therefore,  by  constant 
capital  advanced  for  the  production  of  value,  we  always  mean, 
unless  the  context  is  repugnant  thereto,  the  value  of  the  means 
of  production  actually  consumed  in  the  process,  and  that  value 
alone. 

This  being  so,  let  us  return  to  the  formula  C=^c-i-v,  which 
we  saw  was  transformed  into  C  =(c -h  v) -f  s,  C  becoming  C 
We  know  that  the  value  of  the  constant  capital  is  transferred 
to,  and  merely  re-appears  in  the  product.  The  new  value 
actually  created  in  the  process,  the  value  produced,  or  value- 
product,  is  therefore  not  the  same  as  the  value  of  the  product ; 
it  is  not,  as  it  would  at  first  sight  appear  (c-|-v)-f  s  or  £410 

1  "  If  we  reckon  the  value  of  the  fixed  capital  employed  as  a  part  of  the  advances, 
Tre  must  reckon  the  remaining  value  of  such  capital  at  the  end  of  the  year  as  a  part 
of  the  annual  returns."  (Malthus,  "Princ.  of  Pol.  Econ."2nded.,Lond.,  1836,  p.  269.) 


ig6  Capitalist  Production. 

const.  +  £90  var. 4-^90  surpl.;  bat  v-hs  or  £90  var.-f£90  surpL 
not  £590  but  £180.  If  c=o,  or  in  other  words,  if  there  were 
branches  of  industry  in  which  the  capitahst  could  dispense 
with  all  means  of  production  made  by  previous  labour,  whether 
tliey  be  raw  material,  auxiliary  material,  or  instruments  of 
labour,  employing  only  labour-power  and  materials  supplied 
by  Nature,  in  that  case,  there  would  be  no  constant  capital  to 
transfer  to  the  pn)duct.  This  component  of  the  value  of  the 
product,  Le,y  the  £410  in  our  example,  would  be  eliminated, 
but  the  sum  of  £180,  the  amount  of  new  value  ci^ated,  or  the 
value  produced,  which  contains  £90  of  surplus- value,  would 
remain  just  as  great  as  if  c  represented  the  highest  value 
imaginable.  We  should  have  C=(0+v)=v  or  C  the  expanded 
capital=v-f  s  and  therefore  C — C=s  as  before.  On  the  other 
hand,  if  s=0,  or  in  other  words,  if  the  labour-power,  whose 
value  is  advanced  in  the  form  of  variable  capital,  weie  to  pio- 
duce  only  its  equivalent,  we  should  have  C=c4v  or  C  the 
value  of  the  product==(c-fv)+0  or  C=Cr.  The  capital  advanced 
would,  in  this  case,  not  have  expanded  its  value. 

From  what  has  gone  before,  we  know  that  surplus-value  is 
purely  the  result  of  a  variation  in  the  value  of  v,  of  that  portion 
of  the  capital  which  is  transformed  into  labour-power;  con- 
sequently, V  +  s  =  V  +  v'  or  v  plus  an  increment  of  v.  But  the 
fact  that  it  is  v  alone  that  varies,  and  the  conditions  of  that 
variation,  are  obscured  by  the  circumstance  that  in  consequence 
of  the  increase  in  the  variable  component  of  the  capital,  there 
is  also  an  increase  in  the  sum  total  of  the  advanced  capital.  It 
was  originally  £500  and  becomes  £590.  Therefore  in  order 
that  our  investigation  may  lead  to  accurate  results,  we  must 
make  abstraction  from  that  portion  of  the  value  of  the  pro- 
duct, in  which  constant  capital  alone  appears,  and  consequently 
must  equate  the  constant  capital  to  zero  or  make  c  =  0.  This 
is  merely  an  application  of  a  mathematical  rule,  employed 
\7henever  we  operate  with  constant  and  variable  magnitudes, 
related  to  each  other  by  the  symbols  of  addition  and  sub- 
traction only. 

A  further  difficulty  is  caused  by  the  original  form  of  the 
•variable  capital.     In  our  example,  C'=  £410  const,  +  £90  var 


The  Rate  of  Surplus-value,  197 

+  £00  surpl. ;  but  £90  is  a  given  and  therefore  a  constant 
quantity  ;  hence  it  appears  absurd  to  treat  it  as  variable.  But 
in  fact,  the  terra  £90  var.  is  here  merely  a  symbol  to  show  that 
this  value  undergoes  a  process.  The  portion  of  the  capital  in- 
vested in  the  purchase  of  labour-power  is  a  definite  quantity  of 
materialised  labour,  a  constant  value  like  the  value  of  the 
labour-power  purchased.  But  in  the  process  of  production  the 
place  of  the  £90  is  taken  by  the  labour-power  in  action,  dead 
labour  is  replaced  by  living  labour,  something  stagnant  by 
something  flowing,  a  constant  by  a  variable.  The  result  is  the 
reproduction  of  v  plus  an  increment  of  v.  From  the  point  of 
view  then  of  capitalist  production,  the  whole  process  appears 
as  the  spontaneous  variation  of  the  originally  constant  value, 
which  is  transformed  into  labour-power.  Both  the  process  and 
its  result,  appear  to  be  owing  to  this  value.  If,  therefore,  such 
expressions  as  "  £90  variable  capital,"  or  "  so  much  self- 
expanding  value,"  appear  contradictory,  this  is  only  because 
they  bring  to  the  surface  a  contradiction  immanent  in  capitalist 
production. 

At  first  sight  it  appears  a  strange  proceeding,  to  equate  the 
constant  capital  to  zero.  Yet  it  is  what  we  do  every  day.  If, 
for  example,  we  wish  to  calculate  the  amount  of  England's 
profits  from  the  cotton  industry,  we  first  of  all  deduct  the  sums 
paid  for  cotton  to  the  United  States,  India,  Egypt  and  other 
countries  ;  in  other  words,  the  value  of  the  capital  that  merely 
re-appears  in  the  value  of  the  product,  is  put  =  0. 

Of  course  the  ratio  of  surplus-value  not  only  to  that  portion 
of  the  capital  from  which  it  immediately  springs,  and  whose 
change  of  value  it  represents,  but  also  to  the  sum  total  of  the 
capital  advanced  is  economically  of  very  great  importance. 
We  shall,  therefore,  in  the  third  book,  treat  of  this  ratio  ex- 
haustively. In  order  to  enable  one  portion  of  a  capital  to  ex- 
pand its  value  by  being  converted  into  labour-power,  it  is 
necessary  that  another  portion  be  converted  into  means  of  pro- 
duction. In  order  that  variable  capital  may  perform  its 
function,  constant  capital  must  be  advanced  in  proper  proportion, 
a  proportion  given  by  the  special  technical  conditions  of  each 
labour-process.     The  circumstance,  however,  that  retorts  and 


19^  Capitalist  Production. 

other  vessels,  are  necessary  to  a  chemical  process,  does  not 
compel  the  chemist  to  notice  them  in  the  result  of  his  analysis. 
If  we  look  at  the  means  of  production,  in  their  relation  to  the 
creation  of  value,  and  to  the  variation  in  the  quantity  of  value, 
apart  from  anything  else,  they  appear  simply  as  the  material 
in  which  labour-power,  the  value-creator,  incorporates  itself. 
Neither  the  nature,  nor  the  value  of  this  material  is  of  an}^ 
importance.  The  only  requisite  is  that  there  be  a  sufficient 
supply  to  absorb  the  labour  expended  in  the  process  of  pro- 
duction. Tliat  supply  once  given,  the  material  may  rise  or 
fall  in  value,  or  even  be,  as  land  and  the  sea,  without  any  value 
in  itself;  but  this  will  have  no  influence  on  the  creation  of  value 
or  on  the  variation  in  the  quantity  of  value.^ 

In  the  first  place  then  we  equate  the  constant  capital  to  zero. 
The  capital  advanced  is  consequently  reduced  from  c+v  to  v, 
and  instead  of  the  value  of  the  product  (c+v)4s  we  have  now 
the  value  produced  (v-f s).  Given  the  new  value  produced  = 
fl80,  which  sum  consequently  represents  the  whole  labour  ex- 
pended during  the  process,  then  subtracting  from  it  £90  the 
value  of  the  variable  capital,  we  have  remaining  £90,  the 
amount  of  the  surplus- value.  This  sum  of  £90  or  s  expresses 
the  absolute  quantity  of  surplus-value  produced.  The  relative 
quantity  produced,  or  the  increase  per  cent  of  the  variable 
capital,  is  determined,  it  is  plain,  by  the  ratio  of  the  surplus- 
value  to  the  variable  capital,  or  is  expressed  by  *.  In  our 
example  this  ratio  is  %%,  which  gives  an  increase  of  100  %. 
This  relative  increase  in  the  value  of  the  variable  capital,  or 
the  relative  magnitude  of  the  surplus-value,  I  call,  "  The  rate 
of  surplus- value.'* 

We  have  seen  that  the  labourer,  during  one  portion  of  the 
labour-process,  produces  only  the  value  of  his  labour-power, 
that  is,  the  value  of  Jiis  means  of  subsistence.     Now  since  his 

1  What  Lucretius  says  is  self-evident ;  "  nil  posse  creari  de  nihilo,"  oat  of  nothing, 
nothing  can  be  created.  Creation  of  value  is  transformation  of  labour-power  into 
labour.  Labour-power  itself  is  energy  transferred  to  a  human  organism  by  means  of 
nourishing  matter. 

2  In  the  same  way  that  the  English  use  the  terms  "rate  of  profit,"  "rate  of  in- 
terest." We  shall  see,  in  Book  III.,  that  the  rate  of  profit  is  no  mystery,  so  soon  as 
we  know  the  laws  of  surplus-value.  If  we  reverse  the  process,  we  cannot  compre- 
hend either  the  one  or  the  other. 


7Jw  Rate  of  Stirphis-valtie.  199 

work  forms  part  of  a  system,  based  on  the  social  division  of 
labour,  he  does  not  directly  produce  the  actual  necessaries 
which  he  himself  consumes ;  he  produces  instead  a  particular 
commodity,  yarn  for  example,  whose  value  is  equal  to  the 
value  of  those  necessaries  or  of  the  money  with  which  they 
can  be  bought.  The  portion  of  his  day's  labour  devoted  to 
this  purpose,  will  be  greater  or  less,  in  proportion  to  the  value 
of  the  necessaries  that  he  daily  requires  on  an  average,  or, 
what  amounts  to  the  same  thing,  in  proportion  to  the  labour- 
time  required  on  an  average  to  produce  them.  If  the  value 
of  those  necessaries  represent  on  an  average  the  expenditure 
of  six  hours'  labour,  the  workman  must  on  an  average  work 
for  six  hours  to  produce  that  value.  If  instead  of  working  for 
the  capitalist,  he  worked  independently  on  his  own  account,  he 
would,  other  things  being  equal,  still  be  obliged  to  labour  for 
the  same  number  of  hours,  in  order  to  produce  the  value  of 
his  labour-power,  and  thereby  to  gain  the  means  of  subsistence 
necessary  for  his  conservation  or  continued  reproduction.  But 
as  we  have  seen,  during  that  portion  of  his  day's  labour  in 
which  he  produces  the  value  of  his  labour-power,  say  three 
shillings,  he  produces  only  an  equivalent  for  the  value  of  his 
labour-power  already  advanced  by  the  capitalist ;  the  new 
value  created  only  replaces  the  variable  capital  advanced.  It 
is  owing  to  this  fact,  that  the  production  of  the  new  value  of 
three  shillings  takes  the  semblance  of  a  mere  reproduction. 
That  portion  of  the  working  day,  then,  during  which  this  re- 
production take  place,  I  call  "  necessai^  "  labour- time,  and  the 
labour  expended  during  that  time  I  call  "  necessary  "  labour.^ 
Necessary,  as  regards  the  labourer,  because  independent  of  the 
particular  social  form  of  his  labour ;  necessary,  as  regards 
capital,  and  the  world  of  capitalists,  because  on  the  continued 
existence  of  the  labourer  depends  their  existence  also. 

During  the  second  period   of  the   labcjur-process,  that   in 

1  In  this  work,  we  have,  up  to  now,  employed  the  term  "  necessary  labour-time,"  to 
designate  the  time  necessary  under  given  social  conditions  for  the  production  of  any 
commodity.  Henceforward  we  use  it  to  designate  also  the  time  necessary  for  the 
production  of  the  particular  commodity  labour-power.  The  use  of  one  and  the  same 
technical  term  in  different  senses  is  inconvenient,  but  in  no  science  can  it  be 
altogether  avoided.  Compare,  for  instance,  the  higher  with  the  lower  branches  of 
mathematics. 


200  Capitalist  Production. 

which  his  labour  is  no  longer  necessary  labour,  the  workman, 
it  is  true,  labours,  expends  labour-power;  but  his  labour,  being 
no  longer  necessary  labour,  he  creates  no  value  for  himself. 
He  creates  surplus-value  which,  for  the  capitalist,  has  all  the 
charms  of  a  creation  out  of  nothing.  This  portion  of  the 
working  day,  I  name  surplus  labour-time,  and  to  the  labour 
expended  during  that  time,  I  give  the  name  of  surplus-labour. 
It  is  every  bit  as  important,  for  a  correct  understanding  of 
surplus- value,  to  conceive  it  as  a  mere  congelation  of  surplus- 
labour-time,  as  nothing  but  materialised  surplus-labour,  as  it 
is,  for  a  pi'oper  comprehension  of  value,  to  conceive  it  as  a  mere 
congelation  of  so  many  hours  of  labour,  as  nothing  but  ma- 
terialised labour.  The  essential  difference  between  the  various 
economic  forms  of  society,  between,  for  instance,  a  society 
based  on  slave  labour,  and  one  based  on  wage  labour,  lies  only 
in  the  mode  in  which  this  surplus-labour  is  in  each  case  ex- 
tracted from  the  actual  producer,  the  labourer.^ 

Since,  on  the  one  hand,  the  values  of  the  variable  capital 
and  of  the  labour-power  purchased  by  that  capital  are  equal, 
and  the  value  of  this  labour-power  determines  the  necessary 
portion  of  the  working  day ;  and  since,  on  the  other  hand,  the 
surplus-value  is  determined  by  the  surplus  portion  of  the 
working  day,  it  follows  that  surplus- value  bears  the  same  ratio 
to  variable  capital,  tliat  surplus-labour  does  to  necessary  labour, 
or  in  other  words,  the  rate  of  surplus- value  \  =  neS^^ro^* 
Both  ratios,  ?^  and  i"n>iu8jaT>our  express  the  same  thinor  in  different 

'  V  necessary  labour'         1  O 

ways  ;  in  the  one  case  by  reference  to  materialised,  incorporated 
labour,  in  tlie  other  by  reference  to  living,  fluent  labour. 

The  rate  of  surplus-value  is  therefore  an  exact  expression 

1  Herr  Wilhelm  Thucy elides  Eoscher  has  found  a  mare's  nest.  He  has  made  the 
important  discovery  that  if,  on  the  one  hand,  the  formation  of  surplus-value,  or 
surplus-produce,  and  the  consequent  accumulation  of  capital,  is  now-a-days  due  to 
the  thrift  of  the  capitalist,  on  the  other  hand,  in  the  lowest  stages  of  civilisation  it  is 
the  strong  who  compel  the  weak  to  economise  (1.  c.  p.  78).  To  economise  what  ? 
Labour  ?  Or  superfluous  wealth  that  does  not  exist  ?  What  is  it  that  makes  such 
men  as  Roscher  account  for  the  origin  of  surplus-value,  by  a  mere  rechauffe  of  the 
more  or  less  plausible  excuses  by  the  capitalist,  for  his  appropriation  of  surplus-value  ? 
It  is,  besides  their  real  ignorance,  their  apologetic  dread  of  a  scientific  analysis  of 
value  and  surplus-value,  and  of  obtaining  a  result,  possibly  not  altogether  palatable 
to  the  powers  that  be. 


The  Rate  of  Surphis-value,  201 

for  the  degree  of  exploitation  of  labour-power  by  capital,  or  of 
the  labourer  by  the  capitalist.^ 

We  assumed  in  our  example,  that  the  value  of  the  product 
=£410  const.  +  £90  var.  +  £90  surpL,  and  that  the  capital 
advanced  =  £500.  Since  the  surplus- value  =  £90,  and  the  ad- 
vanced capital  =  £500,  we  should,  according  to  the  usual  way 
of  reckoning,  get  as  the  rate  of  surplus  value  (generally  con- 
founded with  rate  of  profits)  18%,  a  rate  so  low  as  possibly 
to  cause  a  pleasant  surprise  to  Mr.  Carey  and  other  harraon- 
isers.  But  in  truth,  the  rate  of  surplus-value  is  not  equal 
to  ^  cr  -^  but  to  ^  :  thus  it  is  not  i§  but  fg  or  100%,  which 
is  more  than  five  times  the  apparent  degree  of  exploitation. 
Although,  in  the  case  we  have  supposed,  we  are  ignorant  of 
the  actual  length  of  the  working  day,  and  of  the  duration  in 
days  or  weeks  of  the  labour-process,  as  also  of  the  number  of 
labourers  employed,  yet  the  rate  of  surplus-value  ^  accurately 
discloses  to  us,  by  means  of  its  equivalent  expression,  ^2^^^SSr 
the  relation  between  the  two  parts  of  the  working  day.  This 
relation  is  here  one  of  equality,  the  rate  being  100%.  Hence, 
it  is  plain,  the  labourei-,  in  our  example,  works  one  half  of  the 
day  for  himself,  the  other  half  for  the  capitalist. 

The  method  of  calculating  the  rate  of  surplus- value  is  there- 
fore, shortly,  as  follows.  We  take  the  total  value  of  the  product 
and  put  the  constant  capital  which  merely  re-appears  in  it, 
equal  to  zero.  What  remains,  is  the  only  value  that  has,  in  the 
process  of  producing  the  commodity,  been  actually  created.  If 
the  amount  of  surplus-value  be  given,  we  have  only  to  deduct 
it  from  this  remainder,  to  find  the  variable  capital.  And  vice 
versdy  if  the  latter  be  given,  and  we  require  to  find  the  surplus- 
value.  If  both  be  given,  we  have  only  to  perform  the  conclud- 
ing operation,  viz.,  to  calculate  ^,  the  ratio  of  the  surplus- value 
to  the  variable  capital. 

1  Although  the  rate  of  surplus-value  is  an  exact  expression  for  the  degree  of  ex- 
ploitation of  labour-power,  it  is,  in  no  sense,  an  expression  for  the  absolute  amount 
of  exploitation.  For  example,  if  the  necessary  labour  ?=^  5  hours  and  the  surplus- 
labour  =i  5  hours,  the  degree  of  exploitation  is  100%.  The  amount  of  exploitation  is 
here  measured  by  5  hours.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  necessary  labour  ;=  6  hours 
and  the  surplus-labour  ^=  6  hours,  the  degree  of  exploitation  remains,  as  before, 
100%,  while  the  actual  amount  of  exploitation  has  increased  20%,  namely  from  five 
hou  s  to  six. 


2'02  Capitalist  Production, 

Though  the  method  is  so  simple,  yet  it  may  not  be  amiss,  by 
means  of  a  few  examples,  to  exercise  the  reader  in  the  applica- 
tion of  the  novel  principles  underlying  it. 

First  we  will  take  the  case  of  a  spinning  mill  containing 
10,000  mule  spindles,  spinning  No.  32  yarn  from  American 
cotton,  and  producing  1  lb.  of  yarn  weekly  per  spindle.  We 
assume  the  waste  to  be  6  % :  under  these  circumstances  10,600 
lbs.  of  cotton  are  consumed  weekly,  of  which  600  lbs.  go  to 
waste.  The  price  of  the  cotton  in  April,  1871,  was  7|d.  ])er 
lb. ;  the  raw  material  therefo^-e  costs  in  round  numbers  £342. 
The  10,000  spindles,  inchiding  preparation -machinery,  and 
motive  power,  cost,  we  will  assume,  £1  per  spindle,  amounting 
to  a  total  of  £10,000.  The  wear  and  tear  we  put  at  10  %,  or 
£1000  yearly  =:  £20  weekly.  The  rent  of  the  building  we 
suppose  to  be  £300  a  year,  or  £6  a  week.  Coal  consumed  (for 
100  horse-power  indicated,  at  4  lbs.  of  coal  per  horse-power  per 
hour  durinor  60  hours,  and  inclusive  of  that  consumed  in  heatinor 
the  mill),  11  tons  a  week  at  8s.  6d.  a  ton,  amounts  to  about  £4J 
a  week:  gas,  £1  a  week,  oil,«fec.,£4J  a  week.  Total costof  theabove 
auxiliary  materials,  £10  weekly.  Therefore  the  constant  portion 
of  the  value  of  the  week  s  product  is  £378.  Wages  amount 
to  £52  a  week.  The  price  of  the  yarn  is  12Jd.  per  lb.,  which 
gives  for  the  value  of  10,000  lbs.  the  sum  of  £510.  The  surplus 
value  is  therefore  in  this  case  £510  —  £430  ~  £80.  We  put 
the  constant  part  of  the  value  of  the  product  •=.  0,  as  it  plays 
no  part  in  the  creation  of  value.  There  remains  £132  as  the 
weekly  value  cieated,  which  =:  £52  var.  £80  surpl.  The 
rate  of  surplus-value  is  therefore  |o  =  153H  %.  In  a  working 
day  of  10  hours  with  average  labour  the  result  is :  necessary 
labour  =  3f^  hours,  and  surplus-labour  =  61?%.^ 

One  mora  example.  Jacob  gives  the  following  calculation  for 
the  year  1815.  Owing  to  the  previous  adjustment  of  several 
items  it  is  very  imperfect ;  nevertheless  for  our  purpose  it  is 
sufficient.  In  it  he  assumes  the  price  of  wheat  to  be  8s.  a 
quarter,  and  the  average  yield  per  acre  to  be  22  bushels. 

1  The  above  data,  which  may  be  relied  upon,  were  given  me  by  a  Manchester  spinner. 
In  England  the  horse-power  of  an  engine  was  formerly  calculated  from  the  diameter 
of  its  cylinder,  now  the  actual  horse-power  shown  by  the  indicator  is  taken. 


The  Rate  of  Surplus-value.  20, 

Value  Produced  Per  Acre. 


Seed, 

£1     9 

0 

Tithes,  Rates,  and 

Manure, 

2  10 

0 

Taxes,    -        -      £1     1 

0 

Wages, 

3  10 

0 

Rent,          -         -         1     8 
Farmer's  Profit  and 

Interest,          -         12 

Total,  -      £3  11 

0 

0 

Total,  - 

£7     9 



0 

0 

Assuming  that  the  price  of  the  product  is  the  same  as  its 
value,  we  here  find  the  surplus-value  distributed  under  the 
various  heads  of  profit,  interest,  rent,  &c.  We  have  nothing  to 
do  with  these  in  detail ;  we  simply  add  them  together,  and  the 
sum  is  a  surplus- value  of  £3  lis.  Od.  The  sum  of  £3  19s.  Od., 
paid  for  seed  and  manure,  is  constant  capital,  and  we  put  it 
equal  to  zero.  There  is  left  the  sum  of  £3  lOs.  Od.,  which  is 
the  variable  capital  advanced  :  and  we  see  that  a  new  value  of 
£3  lOs.  Od.  +  £3  lis.  Od.  has  been  produced  in  its  place. 
Tlierefore  ~  ==  -||-J^-^;,  giving  a  rate  of  surplus-value  of  more 
than  100  %.  The  labourer  employs  more  than  one  half  of  his 
working  day  in  producing  the  surplus- value,  which  different 
persons,  under  different  pretexts,  share  amongst  themselves.^ 


SECTION  2. — THE  UEPKESENTATION  OF  THE  COMPONENTS  OF  THE  VALUE  OF 
THE  PRODUCT  BY  CORRESPONDING  PROPORTIONAL  PARTS  OF  THE  PRO- 
DUCT ITSELF. 

Let  US  now  return  to  the  example  by  which  we  were  shown 
how  the  capitalist  converts  money  into  capital. 

The  product  of  a  working  day  of  12  hours  is  20  lbs.  of  yarn, 
having  a  value  of  30s.  No  less  than  ^ths  of  this  value,  or  24s., 
is  due  to  mere  re-appearance  in  it,  of  the  value  of  the  means  of 
production  (20  lbs.  of  cotton,  value  20s.,  and  spindle  worn  away, 
4s.)  :  it  is  therefore  constant  capital.  The  remaining  ^ths  or 
6s.  is  the  new  value  created  during  the  spinning  process :  of 

1  The  calculations  given  in  the  text  are  intended  merely  as  illustrations.  We  have 
in  fact  assumed  that  prices  =  values.  We  shall,  however,  see,  in  Book  III.,  that 
even  in  the  case  of  average  prices  the  assumption  cannot  be  made  in  this  very  simple 
manner. 


2Q4  Capitalist  Production, 

this  one  half  replaces  the  value  of  the  day's  labour-power,  or  the 
variable  capital,  the  remaining  half  constitutes  a  surplus-value 
of  3s.  The  total  value  then  of  the  20  lbs.  of  yarn  is  made  up 
as  follows : 

30s.  value  of  yarn  =  24s.  const,  -f  3s.  var.  +  3s.  surpl. 

Since  the  whole  of  this  value  is  contained  in  the  20  lbs.  of 
yarn  produced,  it  follows  that  the  various  component  parts  of 
this  value,  can  be  represented  as  being  contained  respectively 
in  corresponding  parts  of  the  product. 

If  the  value  of  30s.  is  contained  in  20  lbs.  of  yarn,  then  ^  ths 
of  this  value,  or  the  24s.  that  form  its  constant  part,  is  con- 
tained in  ^ths  of  the  product  or  in  16  lbs.  of  yarn.  Of  the 
latter  13J  lbs.  represent  the  value  of  the  raw  material,  the  20s. 
worth  of  cotton  spun,  and  2|  lbs.  represent  the  4s.  worth  of 
spindle,  &c.,  worn  away  in  the  process. 

Hence  the  whole  of  the  cotton  used  up  in  spinning  the  20 
lbs.  of  yarn,  is  represented  by  13 J  lbs.  of  yarn.  This  latter 
weight  of  yarn  contains,  it  is  true,  by  weight,  no  more  than  13J 
lbs.  of  cotton,  worth  13  J  shillings  ;  but  the  6|  shillings  additional 
value  contained  in  it,  are  the  equivalent  for  the  cotton  consumed 
in  spinning  the  remaining  6|  lbs.  of  yarn.  The  effect  is  the 
same  as  if  these  6|  lbs.  of  yarn  contained  no  cotton  at  all,  and 
the  whole  20  lbs.  of  cotton  were  concentrated  in  the  13 J  lbs.  of 
yarn.  The  latter  weight,  on  the  other  hand,  does  not  contain 
an  atom  either  of  the  value  of  the  auxiliary  materials  and  imple- 
ments, or  of  the  value  newly  created  in  the  process. 

In  the  same  way,  the  2|  lbs.  of  yarn,  in  which  the  4s.,  the  re- 
mainder of  the  constant  capital,  is  embodied,  represents  nothing 
but  the  value  of  the  auxiliary  materials  and  instruments  of 
labour  consumed  in  producing  the  20  lbs.  of  yarn. 

We  have,  therefore,  amved  at  this  result :  although  eight- 
tenths  of  the  product,  or  16  lbs.  of  yarn,  is,  in  its  character  of 
an  article  of  utility,  just  as  much  the  fabric  of  the  spinner's 
labour,  as  the  remainder  of  the  same  product,  yet  when  viewed 
in  this  connexion,  it  does  not  contain,  and  has  not  absorbed 
any  labour  expended  during  the  process  of  spinning.  It  is  just 
as  if  the  cotton  had  converted  itself  into  yarn,  without  help  ; 
as  if  the  shape  it  had  assumed  was  mere  trickery  and  deceit : 


The  Rate  of  Siirplus-value,  205 

for  so  soon  as  our  capit-alist  sells  it  for  24s.,  and  with  the  money 
replaces  his  means  of  production,  it  becomes  evident  that  this 
16  lbs.  of  yarn  is  nothing  more  than  so  much  cotton  and  spindle- 
waste  in  disguise. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  remaining  y^  ths  of  the  product,  or  4 
lbs.  of  yarn,  represent  nothing  but  the  new  value  of  6s.,  created 
during  the  12  hours'  spinning  process.  All  the  value  trans- 
ferred to  those  4  lbs.,  from  the  raw  material  and  instruments 
of  labour  consumed,  was,  so  to  say,  intercepted  in  order  to  be 
incorporated  in  the  16  lbs.  first  spun.  In  this  case,  it  is  as  if 
the  spinner  had  spun  4  lbs.  of  yarn  out  of  air,  or,  as  if  he  had 
spun  them  with  the  aid  of  cotton  and  spindles,  that,  being  the 
spontaneous  gift  of  Nature,  transferred  no  value  to  the  product. 

Of  this  4  lbs.  of  yarn,  in  which  the  whole  of  the  value  newly 
created  during  the  process,  is  condensed,  one  half  represents 
the  equivalent  for  the  value  of  the  labour  consumed,  or  the  3s. 
variable  capital,  the  other  half  represents  the  8s.  surplus-value. 

Since  12  workingjiours  of  the  spinner  are  embodied  in  6s., 
it  follows  that  in  yarn  of  the  value  of  30s.,  there  must  be  em- 
bodied 60  working  hours.  And  this  quantity  of  labour-time 
does  in  fact  exist  in  the  20  lbs.  of  yarn  ;  for  in  ^^^ths  or  16  lbs. 
there  are  materialised  the  48  hours  of  labour  expended,  before 
the  commencement  of  the  spinning  process,  on  the  means  of 
production ;  and  in  the  remaining  y^ths  or  4  lbs.  there  are 
materialised  the  12  hours'  work  done  during  the  process  itself 

On  a  former  page  we  saw  that  the  value  of  the  yarn  is  equal 
to  the  sum  of  the  new  value  created  during  the  production  of 
that  yarn  plus  the  value  previously  existing  in  the  means  of 
production. 

It  has  now  been  shown  how  the  various  component  parts  of 
the  value  of  the  product,  parts  that  differ  functionally  from 
each  other,  may  be  represented  by  corresponding  proportional 
parts  of  the  product  itself. 

To  split  up  in  this  manner  the  product  into  different  parts, 
of  which  one  represents  only  the  labour  previously  spent  on 
the  means  of  production,  or  the  constant  capital,  another,  only 
the  necessary  labour  spent  during  the  process  of  production,  or 
the  variable  capital,  and  another  and  last  part,  only -the  surplus- 


2o6  Capitalist  Production. 

labour  expended  during  the  same  process,  or  the  surplus-value  f 
to  do  this,  is,  as  will  be  seen  later  on  from  its  application  to 
complicated  and  hitherto  unsolved  problems,  no  less  impor- 
tant than  it  is  simple. 

In  the  preceding  investigation  we  have  treated  the  total 
product  as  the  final  result,  ready  for  use,  of  a  working  day  of 
12  hours.  We  can  however  follow  this  total  product  through 
all  the  stages  of  its  production  ;  and  in  this  way  we  shall 
arrive  at  the  same  result  as  before,  if  we  represent  the  partial 
products,  given  off  at  the  different  stages,  as  functionally 
different  parts  of  the  final  or  total  product. 

The  spinner  produces  in  12  hours  20  lbs.  of  yarn,  or  in  1 
hour  1|  lbs. ;  consequently  he  produces  in  8  hours  13 J  lbs.,  or 
a  partial  product  equal  in  value  to  all  the  cotton  that  is  spun 
in  a  whole  day.  In  like  manner  the  partial  product  of  the 
next  period  of  1  hour  and  36  minutes,  is  2|  lbs.  of  yarn :  this 
represents  the  value  of  the  instruments  of  labour  that  are  con- 
sumed in  12  hours.  In  the  following  hour  and  12  minutes, 
the  spinner  produces  2  lbs.  of  yarn  worth  3  shillings,  a  value 
equal  to  the  whole  value  he  creates  in  his  6  hours  necessary 
labour.  Finally,  in  the  last  hour  and  12  minutes  he  produces 
another  2  lbs.  of  yarn,  whose  value  is  equal  to  the  surplus- 
value,  created  by  his  surplus-labour  during  half  a  day.  This 
method  of  calculation  serves  the  English  manufacturer  for 
everyday  use ;  it  shows,  he  will  say,  that  in  the  first  8  hours, 
or  f  of  the  working  day,  he  gets  back  the  value  of  his  cotton ; 
and  so  on  for  the  remaining  hours.  It  is  also  a  perfectly 
correct  method:  being  in  fact  the  first  method  given  above 
with  this  difference,  that  instead  of  being  applied  to  space,  in 
which  the  different  parts  of  the  completed  product  lie  side  by 
side,  it  deals  with  time,  in  which  those  parts  are  successively 
produced.  But  it  can  also  be  accompanied  by  very  barbarian 
notions,  more  especially  in  the  heads  of  those  who  are  as  mu*.  h 
interested,  practically,  in  the  process  of  making  value  beget 
value,  as  they  are  in  misunderstanding  that  process  theoreti- 
cally. Such  people  may  get  the  notion  into  their  heads,  that 
our  spinner,  for  example,  produces  or  replaces  in  the  first  8 
hours  of  his  working  day  the  value  of  the  cotton;  in  the 


The  Rate  of  SurphtS'Vahie,  207 

following  hour  and  86  minutes  the  vilue  of  the  instruments  of 
labour  worn  away;  in  the  next  hour  and  12  minutes  the  value 
of  the  wages ;  and  that  he  devotes  to  the  production  of  surplus- 
value  for  the  manufacturer,  only  that  well  known  **  last  hour." 
In  this  way  the  poor  spinner  is  made  to  perform  the  two-fold 
miracle  not  only  of  producing  cotton,  spindles,  steam-engine, 
coal,  oil,  fee,  at  the  same  time  that  he  spins  with  them,  but 
also  of  turning  one  working  day  into  five  ;  for,  in  the  example 
we  are  considering,  the  production  of  the  raw  material  and  instru- 
ments of  labour  demands  four  working  days  of  twelve  hours 
each,  and  their  conversion  into  yarn  requires  another  such  day. 
That  the  love  of  lucre  induces  an  easy  belief  in  such  miracles, 
and  that  sycophant  doctrinaires  are  never  wanting  to  prove 
them,  is  vouched  for  by  the  following  incident  of  historical 
celebrity. 


SECTION  3. — senior's  "  LAST  HOUR.** 

One  fine  morning,  in  the  year  1 836,  Nassau  W.  Senior,  who 
may  be  called  the  bel-esprit  of  English  economists,  well  known, 
alike  for  his  economical  "science,"  and  for, his  beautiful  style, 
was  summoned  from  Oxford  to  Manchester,  to  learn  in  the 
latter  place,  the  political  economy  that  he  taught  in  the  former. 
The  manufacturers  elected  him  as  their  champion,  not  only 
against  the  newly  passed  Factory  Act,  but  against  the  still 
more  menacing  Ten-hours'  agitation.  With  their  usual  practical 
acuteness,  they  had  found  out  that  the  learned  Professor 
"wanted  a  good  deal  of  finishing;"  it  was  this  discovery  that 
caused  them  to  write  for  him.  On  his  side  the  Professor  has 
embodied  the  lecture  he  received  from  the  Manchester  manu- 
facturers, in  a  pamphlet,  entitled  :  "  Letters  on  the  Factory 
Act,  as  it  affects  the  cotton  manufacture."  London,  1837. 
Here  we  find,  amongst  others,  the  following  edifying  passage : 
"  Under  the  present  law,  no  mill  in  which  persons  under  18 

years  of  age  are  employed, can  be  worked  more 

than  \\\  hours  a  day,  that  is,  12  hours  for  5  days  in  the  week, 
and  nine  on  Saturday. 

"  Now  the  following  analysis  (!)  will  show  that  in  a  mill  so 


2o8  Capitalist  Production, 

worked,  the  whole  net  profit  is  derived  from  the  last  hour.  I 
will  suppose  a  manufacturer  to  invest  £100,000  : — £80,000  in 
his  mill  and  machinery,  and  £20,000  in  raw  material  and  wages. 
The  annual  return  of  that  mill,  supposing  the  capital  to  be 
turned  once  a  year,  and  gross  profits  to  be  15  per  cent.,  ought 

to  be  goods  worth  £115,000 Of  this  £115,000, 

each  of  the  twenty- three  half-hours  of  work  produces  5-115ths 
or  one  twenty -third.  Of  these  23-23rds  (constituting  the  whole 
£115,000)  twenty,  that  is  to  say  £100,000  out  of  the  £115,000, 
simply  replace  the  capital; — one  twenty-third  (or  £5000  out 
of  the  £115,000)  makes  up  for  the  deterioration  of  the  mill  and 
machinery.  The  remaining  2-23rds,  that  is,  the  last  two  of  the 
twenty-three  half-hours  of  every  day,  produce  the  net  profit  of 
10  per  cent.  If,  therefore  (prices  remaining  the  same),  the 
factory  could  be  kept  at  work  thirteen  hours  instead  of  eleven 
and  a  half,  with  an  addition  of  about  £2600  to  the  circulating 
capital,  the  net  profit. would  be  more  than  doubled.  On  the 
other  hand,  if  the  hours  of  working  were  reduced  by  one  hour 
per  day  (prices  remaining  the  same),  the  net  profit  would  be 
destroyed — if  they  were  reduced  by  one  hour  and  a  half,  even 
the  gross  profit  would  be  destroyed."  ^ 

1  Senior,  1.  c,  p.  12,  13.  We  let  pass  such  extraordinary  notions  as  are  of  no  im- 
portance for  our  purpose ;  for  instance,  the  assertion,  that  manufacturers  reckon  as 
part  of  their  profit,  gross  or  net,  the  amount  required  to  make  good  wear  and  tear  of 
machinery,  or  in  other  words,  to  replace  a  part  of  the  capital.  So.  too,  we  pass  over 
any  question  as  to  the  accuracy  of  his  figures.  Leonard  Horner  has  shown  in  "A 
Letter  to  Mr.  Senior,"  &c.,  London,  1837,  that  they  are  worth  no  more  than  the  so- 
called  "  Analysis."  Leonard  Horner  was  one  of  the  Factory  Inquiry  Commissioners 
in  1833,  and  Inspector,  or  rather  Censor  of  Factories  till  1859.  He  rendered  undying 
service  to  the  English  working  class.  He  carried  on  a  life-long  contest,  not  only 
with  the  embittered  manufacturers,  but  also  with  the  Cabinet,  to  whom  the  number 
of  votes  given  by  the  masters  in  the  Lower  House,  was  a  matter  of  far  greater  impor- 
tance than  the  number  of  hours  worked  by  the  "  hands  "  in  the  mills. 

Apart  from  errors  in  j)rinciple,  Senior's  statement  is  confused.  "WTiat  he  really  in- 
tended to  say  was  this  :  The  manufacturer  employs  the  workman  for  11^  hours  or  for 
23  half-hours  daily.  As  the  working  day,  so,  too,  the  working  year,  may  be  conceived 
to  consist  of  11.^  hours  or  23  half -hours,  but  each  multiplied  by  the  number  of  working 
days  in  the  year.  On  this  supposition,  the  23  half -hours  yield  an  annual  product  of 
£115,000;  one  half -hour  yields  ^V  x  £115,000;  20  half -hours  yield  |g  x  £115,000; 
=  £100,000,  i.e.,  they  replace  no  more  than  the  capital  advanced.  There  remain  3  half- 
hours,  which  yield  ^^5  x  £115,000= £15,000  or  the  gross  i>rofit.  Of  these  3  half -hours,  one 
yields  oV  x  £115,000  =  £5000  ;  i.e.,  it  makes  up  for  the  wear  and  tear  of  the 
machinery  ;  the  remaining  2  half -hours,  i.e.,  the  last  hour,  yield  ^\  x  £115,000  = 
£10,000  or  the  net  profit.  In  the  text  Senior  converts  the  last  -^^  of  the  product  into 
portions  of  the  working  day  itself. 


The  Rate  of  Surplus-value,  209 

And  the  professor  calls  this  an  "  analysis ! "  If,  giving 
credence  to  the  out-cries  of  the  manufacturers,  he  believed  that 
the  workmen  spend  the  best  part  of  the  day  in  the  production, 
i.e.y  the  reproduction  or  replacement  of  the  value  of  the  build- 
ings, machinery,  cotton,  coal,  &;c.,  then  his  analysis  was  super- 
fluous. His  answer  would  simply  have  been  : — Gentlemen  ! 
if  you  work  your  mills  for  10  hours  instead  of  11|,  then,  other 
things  being  equal,  the  daily  consumption  of  cotton,  machinery, 
&;c.,  will  decrease  in  proportion.  You  gain  just  as  much  as 
you  lose.  Your  work-people  will  in  future  spend  one  hour 
and  a  half  less  time  in  reproducing  or  replacing  the  capital 
that  has  been  advanced. — If,  on  the  other  hand,  he  did  not 
believe  them  without  further  inquiry,  but,  as  being  an  expert 
in  such  matters,  deemed  an  analysis  necessary,  then  he  ought, 
in  a  question  that  is  concerned  exclusively  with  the  relations 
of  net  profit  to  the  length  of  the  working  day,  before  all  things 
to  have  asked  the  manufacturers,  to  be  careful  not  to  lump 
together  machinery,  workshops,  raw  material,  and  labour,  but 
to  be  good  enough  to  place  the  constant  capital,  invested  in 
buildings,  machinery,  raw  material,  &ic.,  on  one  side  of  the 
account,  and  the  capital  advanced  in  wages  on  the  other  side. 
If  the  profesvsor  then  found,  that  in  accordance  with  the  calcu- 
lation of  the  manufacturers,  the  workman  reproduced  or  re- 
placed his  wages  in  2  half-hours,  in  that  case,  he  should  have 
continued  his  analysis  thus  : 

According  to  your  figures,  the  workman  in  the  last  hour  but 
one  produces  his  wages,  and  in  the  last  hour  your  surplus- 
value  or  net  profit.  Now,  since  in  equal  periods  he  produces 
equal  values,  the  produce  of  the  last  hour  but  one,  must  have 
the  same  value  as  that  of  the  last  hour.  Further,  it  is  only 
while  he  labours  that  he  produces  any  value  at  all,  and  the 
amount  of  his  labour  is  measured  by  his  labour-time.  This 
you  say,  amounts  to  11 J  hours  a  day.  He  employs  one  portion 
of  these  11 J  hours,  in  producing  or  replacing  his  wages,  and  the 
remaining  portion  in  producing  your  net  profit.  Beyond  this  he 
does  absolutely  nothing.  But  since,  on  your  assumption,  his 
wages,  and  the  surplus-value  he  yields,  are  of  equal  value,  it 
is  clear  that  he  produces  his  wages  in  5|  hours,  and  your  net 


^210  Capitalist  Production. 

profit  in  the  other  oj  hours.  Again,  since  the  value  of  the 
yarn  produced  in  2  hours,  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  the  values  of 
his  wages  and  of  your  net  profit,  the  measure  of  the  value  of 
this  yarn  must  be  II2  working  hours,  of  which  5f  hours 
measure  the  value  of  the  yarn  produced  in  the  last  hour  bub 
one,  and  5f,  the  value  of  the  yarn  produced  in  the  last  hour. 
We  now  come  to  a  ticklish  point ;  therefore,  attention  !  The 
last  working  hour  but  one  is,  like  the  first,  an  ordinary  working 
hour,  neither  more  nor  less.  How  then  can  the  spinner  pro- 
duce in  one  hour,  in  the  shape  of  yarn,  a  value  that  embodies 
5f  hours  labour  ?  The  truth  is  that  he  performs  no  such 
miracle.  The  use-value  produced  by  him  in  one  hour,  is  a 
definite  quantity  of  yarn.  The  vakie  of  this  yarn  is  measured 
by  5f  working  hours,  of  which  4f  were,  without  any  assistance 
from  him,  previously  embodied  in  the  means  of  production,  in 
the  cotton,  the  machinery,  and  so  on  ;  the  remaining  one  hour 
alone  is  added  by  him.  Therefore  since  his  wages  are  produced 
in  5f  hours,  and  the  yarn  produced  in  one  hour  also  contains 
5|  hours'  work,  there  is  no  witchcraft  in  the  result,  that  the 
value  created  by  his  5|  hours*  spinning,  is  equal  to  the  value  of 
the  product  spun  in  one  hour.  You  are  altogether  on  the 
wrong  track,  if  you  think  that  he  loses  a  single  moment  of  his 
working  day,  in  reproducing  or  replacing  the  values  of  the 
cotton,  the  machinery,  and  so  on:  On  the  contrary,  it  is  be- 
cause his  labour  converts  the  cotton  and  spindles  into  yarn, 
because  he  spins,  that  the  values  of  the  cotton  and  spindles  go 
over  to  the  yarn  of  their  oww  accord.  This  result  is  owing  to 
the  quality  of  his  labour,  not  to  its  quantity.  It  is  true,  he 
will  in  one  hour  transfer  to  the  yarn  more  value,  in  the  shape 
of  cotton,  than  he  will  in  half  an  hour ;  but  that  is  only  be- 
cause in  one  hour  he  spins  up  more  cotton  than  in  half  an 
hour.  You  see  then,  your  assertion,  that  the  workman  pro- 
duces, in  the  last  hour  but  one,  the  value  of  his  wages,  and  in 
the  last  hour  your  net  profit,  amounts  to  no  more  than  this, 
that  in  the  yarn  produced  by  him  in  2  working  hours,  whether 
they  are  the  2  first  or  the  2  last  hours  of  the  working  day,  in 
that  yarn,  there  are  incorporated  11^  working  hours,  or  just  a 
whole  day's  work,  Le.y  two  hours  of  his  own  work  and  9^  hours 


The  Rate  of  Surplus-vahie.  2 1 1 

of  other  people's.  And  my  assertion  that,  in  the  first  5f  hours, 
he  produces  his  wages,  and  in  the  last  5|  hours  your  net  profit, 
amounts  only  to  this,  that  you  pay  him  for  the  former,  but  not 
for  the  latter.  In  speaking  of  payment  of  labour,  instead  of 
payment  of  labour-power,  I  only  talk  your  own  slang.  Now, 
gentlemen,  if  you  compare  the  working  time  you  pay  for,  with 
that  which  yow.  do  not  pay  for,  you  will  find  that  they  are  to 
one  another,  as  half  a  day  is  to  half  a  day  ;  this  gives  a  rate  of 
100%,  and  a  very  pretty  percentage  it  is.  Further,  there  is 
not  the  least  doubt,  that  if  you  make  your  "  hands  "  toil  for  13 
hours,  instead  of  11  J,  and,  as  may  be  expected  from  you,  treat 
the  work  done  in  that  extra  one  hour  and  a  half,  as  pure 
surplus-labour,  then  the  latter  will  be  increased  from  5|  hours' 
labour  to  7i  hours'  labour,  and  the  rate  of  surplus-value  from 
100%  to  126  4  %•  So  that  you  are  altogether  too  sanguine,  in 
expecting  that  by  such  an  addition  of  1|  hours  to  the  working 
day,  the  rate  will  rise  from  100%  to  200%  and  more,  in  other 
words  that  it  will  be  "more  than  doubled."  On  the  other 
hand — man's  heart  is  a  wonderful  thing,  especially  when 
carried  in  the  purse — you  take  too  pessimist  a  view,  when  you 
fear,  that  with  a  reduction  of  the  hours  of  labour  from  \\\  to 
10,  the  whole  of  your  net  profit  will  go  to  the  dogs.  Not  at 
all.  All  other  conditions  remaining  the  same,  the  surplus- 
labour  will  fall  from  5|  hours  to  4|  hours,  a  period  that  still 
gives  a  very  profitable  rate  of  surplus-value,  namely  82^^  %. 
But  this  dreadful  "  last  hour,"  about  which  you  have  invented 
more  stories  than  have  the  millenarians  about  the  day  of 
judgment,  is  "all  bosh."  If  it  goes,  it  will  cost  neither  you, 
your  net  profit,  nor  the  boys  and  girls  whom  you  employ,  their 
"  purity  of  mind."  ^      Whenever  your  "  last  hour  "  strikes  in 

1  If,  on  the  one  hand,  Senior  proved  that  the  net  profit  of  the  manufacturer, 
the  existence  of  the  English  cotton  industry,  and  England's  command  of  the  markets 
of  the  Wi)rld,  depend  on  "  the  last  working  hour,"  on  the  other  hand,  Dr.  Andrew 
Ure  showed,  that  if  children  and  young  persons  under  18  years  of  age,  instead  of  being 
kept  the  full  12  hours  in  the  warm  and  pure  moral  atmosphere  of  the  factory,  are 
turned  out  an  hour  sooner  into  the  heartless  and  frivolous  outer  world,  they  will  be 
deprived,  by  idleness  and  vice,  of  all  hope  of  salvation  for  their  souls.  Since  1848,  the 
factory  inspectors  have  never  tired  of  twitting  the  masters  with  this  "  last,"  this 
"fatal  hour."  Thus  Mr.  Howell  in  his  report  of  the  81st  May,  1855:  "Had  the  follow- 
ing ingenious  calculation  (he  quotes  Senior)  been  correct,  every  cotton  factory  in  the 
United  Kingdom  would  have  been  working  at  a  loss  since  the  year  1850."    (Reports 


212  Capitalist  Production. 

earnest,  think  on  the  Oxford  Professor.  And  now,  gentleman, 
"  farewell,  and  may  we  meet  again  in  yonder  better  world,  but 
not  before/' 

Senior  invented  the  battle  cry  of  the  "  last  hour  "  in  1836.* 

of  the  Insp,  of  Fact,  for  the  half-year,  ending  30th  April,  1855,  pp.  19,  20.)  In  the 
year  1848,  after  the  passing  of  the  10  hour's  bill,  the  masters  of  some  flax  siiinning 
mills,  scattered,  few  and  far  between,  over  the  country  on  the  borders  of  Dorset  and 
Somerset,  foisted  a  petition  against  the  bill  on  to  the  shoulders  of  a  few  of  their  work 
people.  One  of  the  clauses  of  this  petition  is  as  follows  :  ' '  Your  petitioners,  as 
parents,  conceive  that  an  additional  hour  of  leisure  will  tend  more  to  demoralise  the 
children  than  otherwise,  believing  that  idleness  is  the  parent  of  vice. "  On  this  the 
factory  report  of  31st  Oct.,  1848,  says :  The  atmosphere  of  the  flax  mills,  in  which  the 
children  of  these  virtuous  and  tender  parents  work,  is  so  loaded  with  dust  and  fibre 
from  the  raw  material,  that  it  is  exceptionally  unpleasant  to  stand  even  10  minutes  in 
the  spinning  rooms  :  for  you  are  unable  to  do  so  without  the  most  painful  sensation, 
owing  to  the  eyes,  the  ears,  the  nostrils,  and  mouth,  being  immediately  filled  by  the 
clouds  of  flax  dust  from  which  there  is  no  escape.  The  labour  itself,  owing  to  the 
feverish  haste  of  the  machinery,  demands  unceasing  application  of  skill  and  movement, 
under  the  control  of  a  watchfulness  that  never  tires,  and  it  seems  somewhat  hard,  to 
let  parents  apply  the  term  "idling"  to  their  own  children,  who,  after  allowing  for 
meal  times,  are  fettered  for  10  whole  hours  to  such  an  occupation,  in  such  an  atmos- 
phere.    .     .     .     These  children  work  longer  than  the  labourers  in  the  neighbouring 

villages Such  cruel   talk  about   *'  idleness  and  vice  "   ought  to  be 

branded  as  the  purest  cant,  and  the  most  shameless  hypocrisy That 

portion  of  the  public,  who,  about  12  years  ago,  were  struck  by  the  assurance  with 
which,  under  the  sanction  of  high  authority,  it  was  publicly  and  most  earnestly  pro- 
claimed, that  the  whole  net  profit  of  the  manufacturer  flows  from  the  labour  of  the 
last  hour,  and  that,  therefore,  the  reduction  of  the  working  day  by  one  hour,  would 
destroy  his  net  profit ,  that  portion  of  the  public,  we  say,  will  hardly  believe  its  own 
eyes,  when  it  now  finds,  that  the  original  discovery  of  the  virtues  of  "  the  last  hour  " 
has  si  ce  been  so  far  improved,  as  to  include  morals  as  well  as  profit ;  so  that,  if  the 
duration  of  the  labour  of  children,  is  reduced  to  a  full  10  hours,  their  morals,  together 
with  the  net  profits  of  their  employers,  will  vanish,  both  being  dependent  on  this  last, 
this  fatal  hour.  (See  Repts.,  Insp.  of  Fact.,  for  31st  Oct.,  1848,  p.  101.)  The  same 
report  then  gives  some  examples  of  the  morality  and  virtue  of  these  same  pure-minded 
manufacturers,  of  the  tricks,  the  artifices,  the  cajoling,  the  threats,  and  the  falsifica- 
tions, they  made  use  of,  in  order,  first,  to  compel  a  few  defenceless  workmen  to  sign 
petitions  of  such  a  kind,  and  then  to  impose  them  upon  Parliament  as  the  petitions 
of  a  whole  branch  of  industry,  or  a  whole  country.  It  is  highly  characteristic  of  the 
present  status  of  so  called  economical  science,  that  neither  Senior  himself,  who,  at  a 
later  period,  to  his  honour  be  it  said,  energetically  supported  the  factory  legislation, 
nor  his  opponents,  from  first  to  last,  have  ever  been  able  to  explain  the  false  con- 
clusions of  the  '*  original  discovery."  They  appeal  to  actual  experience,  but  the  why 
and  wherefore  remains  a  mystery. 

I  Nevertheless,  the  learnel  professor  was  not  without  some  benefit  from  his  journey 
to  Manchester.  In  the  "  Letters  on  the  Factory  Act,"  he  makes  the  whole  net  gains 
including  "  profit  "  and  "  interest, "and  even  "something more,"  depend  upon  a  single 
unpaid  hour's  work  of  the  labourer.  One  year  previously,  in  his  "Outlines  of  Political 
Economy,"  written  for  the  instruction  of  Oxford  students  and  cultivated  Philistines, 
ho  had  also  "  discovered,  in  opposition  to  Ricardo's  determination  of  value  by  labour, 
that  profit  is  derived  from  the  labour  of  the  capitalist,  and  interest  from  his  asceticism, 


The  Rate  of  Siirplus-valiie.  213 

In  the  London  Fconoraist  of  the  15th  April,  1848,  the  same  cry 
was  again  raised  by  James  Wilson,  an  economical  mandarin  of 
high  standing:  this  time  in  opposition  to  the  10  hours'  bill. 

SECTIOJf  4. — SURPLUS-PRODUCE. 

The  position  of  the  product  that  represents  the  surplus-value, 
(one* tenth  of  the  20  lbs,,  or  2  lbs.  of  yarn,  in  the  example  given 
in  Sec.  2.)  we  call  "  surplus-produce,"  Just  as  the  rate  of 
surplus-value  is  determined  by  its  relation,  not  to  the  sum  total 
of  the  capital,  but  to  its  variable  part ;  in  like  manner,  the  re- 
lative quantity  of  surplus-produce  is  determined  by  the  ratio 
that  this  produce  bears,  not  to  the  remaining  part  of  the  total 
product,  but  to  that  part  of  it  in  which  is  incorporated  the 
necessary  labour.  Since  the  production  of  surplus- value  is  the 
chief  end  and  aim  of  capitalist  production,  it  is  clear,  that  the 
greatness  of  a  man's  or  a  nation's  wealth  should  be  measured, 
not  by  the  absolute  quantity  produced,  but  by  the  relative 
magnitude  of  the  surplus-produce.'^ 

The  sum  of  the  necessary  labour  and  the  surplus-labour,  i.e.y 
of  the  periods  of  time  during  which  the  workman  replaces  the 
value  of  his  labour-power,  and  produces  the  surplus-value,  this 
sum  constitutes  the  actual  time  during  which  he  works,  i.e.,  the 
working  da}'. 

in  other  words,  from  hw  "abstinence,'*  The  dodge  was  an  old  one,  but  the  word 
*  *  abstinence  "  was  new.  Herr  Roscher  tra  slates  it  rightly  by  "  Enthaltung. "  Some  of 
his  countrymen,  the  Browns,  Jones,  and  Robinsons,  of  Germany,  not  so  well  versed 
in  Latin  as  he,  have,  monk-like,  rendered  it  by  "Entsagung"  (renunciation). 

I  '*  To  an  individual  with  a  capital  of  £20,000,  whose  profits  were  £2000  per  annum, 
it  would  be  a  matter  quite  indifferent  whether  his  ca})ital  would  employ  a  100  or  1030 
men,  whether  the  commodity  produced  sold  for  £10,000  or  £20,000,  provided,  in  all 
cases,  his  profit  were  not  diminished  below  £2000.  Is  not  the  real  interest  of  the  nation 
similar?  Provided  its  net  real  income,  its  rent  and  profits,  be  the  same,  it  is  of  no 
importance  whether  the  nation  consists  of  10  or  of  12  millions  of  inhabitants.'*  (Rio. 
1.  c,  p.  416.)  Long  before  Ricardo,  Arthur  Young,  a  fanatical  upholder  of  surplus 
produce,  for  the  rest,  a  rambling,  uncritical  writer,  whose  reputation  is  in  the  inverse 
ratio  of  his  merit,  says,  "Of  what  use,  in  a  modern  kingdom,  would  be  a  whole  pro- 
vince thus  divided  [in  the  old  Roman  manner,  by  small  independent  peasants],  however 
well  cultivated,  except  for  the  mere  purpose  of  breeding  men,  which  taken  singly  is  a 
moat  useless  purpose?*'  (Arthur  Young;  Political  Arithmetic,  &c.  London,  1774, 
p.  47.) 

Very  curious  is  "  the  strong  inclination  ...  to  represent  net  wealth  as  beneficial  to 
the  labouring  class  ....  though  it  is  evidently  not  on  account  of  being  net."  (Th. 
Hopkins,  On  Rent  of  Land,  &c.     London,  1823,  p.  126.) 


214  Capitalist  Production, 


CHAPTER  X. 

THE  WORKING  DAY. 

SECTION  1. — THE   LIMITS   OF   THE   WORKING    DAY. 

We  started  with  the  supposition  that  labour-power  is  bought 
and  sold  at  its  value.  Its  value,  like  that  of  all  other  commo- 
dities, is  determined  by  the  working  time  necessary  to  its 
production.  If  the-  prod-uction  of  the  average  daily  means  of 
subsistence  of  the  labourer  takes  up  6  hours,  he  must  work,  on 
the  average,  G  hours  every  day,  to  produce  liis  daily  labour- 
power,  or  to  reproduce  the  value  received  as  the  result  of  its 
sale.  The  necessary  part  of  his  working  day  amounts  to  6 
hours,  and  is,  therefore,  coeteris  paribus,  a  given  quantity.  But 
with  this,  the  extent  of  the  working  day  itself  is  not  yet 
given. 

Let  us  assume  that  the  line  A  B  represents  the  length  of  the 
necessary  working  time,  say  6  hours.  If  the  labour  be  pro- 
longed 1,  3,  or  6  hours  beyond  A  B,  we  have  3  other  lines : 

Working  day  I.  Working  day  II.  Working  day  III. 

A B— C.      A B C.     A B C. 

representing  3  different  working  days  of  7,  9,  and  12  hours. 
The  extension  B  C  of  the  line  A  B  represents  the  length  of 
the  surplus  labour.  As  the  working  day  is  A  B4B  C  or 
A  C,  it  varies  with  the  variable  quantity  B  C.  Since  A  B 
is  constant,  the  ratio  of  B  C  to  A  B  can  always  be  calculated. 
In  working  day  I.  it  is  J,  in  working  day  II,  ~  in  working  day 
111,-1  of  A  B.  Since,  further,  the  ratio  i:£SL!p||J™|.  deter- 
mines  the  rate  of  the  surplus-value,  the  latter  is  given  by  the 
ratio  of  B  C  to  A  B.  It  amounts  in  the  3  different  working 
days  respectively  to  16|,  50  and  100  per  cent.  On  the  other 
hand,  the  rate  of  surplus- value  alone  would  not  give  us  the 
extent  of  the  working  day.  If  this  rate,  e.g.,  were  100  per 
cent.,  the  working  day  might  be  of  8,  10,  12,  or  more  hours. 
It  would  indicate  that  the  2  constituent  parts  of  the  working 


The   Working  Day,  215 

(lay,  iiecessary-lahour  and  surplus-labour  time,  were  equal  in  ex- 
tent, but  not  how  long  each  of  these  two  constituent  parts  was. 

The  working  day  is  thus  not  a  constant,  but  a  variable 
quantity.  One  of  its  parts,  certainly,  is  determined  by  the 
working  time  required  for  the  reproduction  of  the  labour- 
power  of  the  labourer  himself.  But  its  total  amount  varies 
with  the  duration  of  the  surplus-labour.  The  working  day  is, 
therefore,  determinable,  but  is,  'per  se,  indeterminate.  ^ 

Although  the  working  day  is  not  a  fixed,  but  a  fluent 
quantity,  it  can,  on  the  other  hand,  only  vary  within  certain 
limits.  The  minimum  limit  is,  however,  not  determinable  ; 
of  course,  if  we  make  the  extension  line  BC  or  the  surplus- 
labour  =0,  we  have  a  minimum  limit,  i.e.,  the  part  of  the  day 
which  the  labourer  must  necessarily  work  for  his  own  main- 
tenance. On  the  basis  of  capitalist  production,  however,  this 
necessary  labour  can  form  a  part  only  of  the  working  day  ;  the 
working  day  itself  can  never  be  reduced  to  this  minimum.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  working  day  has  a  maximum  limit.  It 
cannot  be  prolonged  beyond  a  certain  point.  This  maximum 
limit  is  conditioned  by  two  things.  First,  by  the  physical 
bounds  of  labour-power.  Within  the  24  hours  of  the  natural  day 
a  man  can  expend  only  a  definite  quantity  of  his  vital  force.  A 
horse,  in  like  manner,  can  only  work  from  day  to  day,  8  hours. 
During  part  of  the  day  this  force  must  rest,  sleep ;  during 
another  part  the  man  has  to  satisfy  other  physical  needs,  to 
feed,  wash,  and  clothe  himself  Besides  these  purely  physical 
limitations,  the  extension  of  the  working  day  encounters 
moral  ones.  The  labourer  needs  time  for  satisfying  his  intellec- 
tual and  social  wants,  the  extent  and  number  of  which  are 
conditioned  by  the  general  state  of  social  advancement.  The 
variation  of  the  working  day  fluctuates,  therefore,  within 
physical  and  social  bounds.  But  both  these  limiting  conditions 
are  of  a  very  elastic  nature,  and  allow  the  greatest  latitude. 
So  we  find  working  days  of  8,  10,  12,  14, 16,  18  hours,  i.e.,  of 
the  most  diflerent  lengths. 

The  capitalist  has  bought  the  labour-power  at  its  day-rate. 

1  "A  day's  labour  is  vague,  it  may  be  long  or  short."    (*'  An  essay  on  Trade  and 
Commerce,  containi'ic  observations  on  taxes,"  &c.     London,  1770,  p.  73.) 


2x6  Capitalist  Production, 

To  him  its  use-value  belongs  during  one  working  day.  He 
has  thus  acquired  the  right  to  make  the  labourer  work  for  him 
during  one  day.     But,  what  is  a  working  day  ? 

At  all  events,  less  than  a  natural  day.  By  how  much  ? 
The  capitalist  has  his  own  views  of  this  ultima  Thile,  the 
necessary  limit  of  the  working  day.  As  capitalist,  he  is  only 
capital  personified.  His  soul  is  the  soul  of  capital.  But 
capital  has  one  single  life  impulse,  the  tendency  to  create 
value  and  surplus- value,  to  make  its  constant  factor,  the  means 
of  production,  absorb  the  greatest  possible  amount  of  surplus- 
labour.  ^ 

Capital  is  dead  labour,  that,  vampire-like,  only  lives  by 
sucking  living  labour,  and  lives  the  more,  the  more  labour  it 
sucks.  The  time  during  which  the  labourer  works,  is  the  time 
during  which  the  capitalist  consumes  the  labour-power  he  has 
purchased  of  him.  ^ 

If  the  labourer  consumes  his  disposable  time  for  himself,  he 
robs  the  capitalist. 

The  capitalist  then  takes  his  stand  on  the  law  of  the  ex- 
change of  commodities.  He,  like  all  other  buyers,  seeks  to  get 
the  greatest  possible  benefit  out  of  the  use-value  of  his  commo- 
dity. Suddenly  the  voice  of  the  labourer,  which  had  been 
stifled  in  the  storm  and  stress  of  the  process  of  production, 
rises : 

The  commodity  that  1  have  sold  to  you  differs  from  the 
crowd  of  other  commodities,  in  that  its  use  creates  value,  and 

1  This  question  is  far  more  important  than  the  celebrated  question  of  Sir  Robert 
Peel  to  the  Birmingham  Chamber  of  Commerce  :  What  is  a  pound?  A  question 
that  could  only  have  been  proposed,  because  Peel  was  as  much  in  the  dark  as  to  the 
nature  of  money  as  the  "  little  shilling  men  "  of  Birmingham. 

2  It  is  the  aim  of  the  capitalist  to  obtain  with  his  expended  capital  the  greatest 
possible  quantity  of  labour  (d'obtenir  du  capital  depens6  la  plus  forte  somme  de 
travail  possible. )  J.  G.  Courcelle-Seneuil.  Traite  theorique  et  pratique  des  entre- 
prises  industrielles.     2nd  ed.     Paris,  1857,  p.  63. 

3  "An  hour's  labour  lost  in  a  day  is  a  prodigious  injury  to  a  commercial  State. 
.  .  .  There  is  a  very  great  consumption  of  luxuries  among  the  labouring  poor  of  this 
kingdom :  particularly  among  the  manufacturing  populace,  by  which  they  also 
consume  their  time,  the  most  fatal  of  consumptions."  An  Essay  on  Trade  and 
Commerce,  &c.,  p.  47  and  153. 

4 "Si  le  manouvrier  libre  prend  un  instant  de  reposjl'economie  sordidequi  le  sixit 
des  yeux  avec  inquietude,  pretend  qu'il  la  vole.''  N.  Linguet.  "Th^orie  des  loix 
civiles,  &c.     London,  17G7,"  t.  II.,  p.  466. 


The   Working  Day.  217 

a  value  greater  than  its  own.  That  is  why  you  bought  it. 
That  which  on  your  side  appears  a  spontaneous  expansion  of 
capital,  is  on  mine  extra  expenditure  of  labour-power.  You 
and  I  know  on  the  market  only  one  law,  that  of  the  exchange 
of  commodities.  And  the  consumption  of  the  commodity 
belongs  not  to  the  seller  who  parts  with  it,  but  to  the  buyer, 
who  acquires  it.  To  you,  therefore,  belongs  the  use  of  my 
daily  labour-power.  But  by  means  of  the  price  that  you  pay 
for  it  each  day,  I  must  be  able  to  reproduce  it  daily,  and  to 
sell  it  again.  Apart  from  natural  exhaustion  through  age,  &c., 
I  must  be  able  on  the  morrow  to  work  with  the  same  normal 
amount  of  force,  health  and  freshness  as  to-day.  You  preach 
to  me  constantly  the  gospel  of  "saving"  and  "abstinence." 
Good  !  I  will,  like  a  sensible  saving  owner,  husband  my  sole 
wealth,  labour-power,  and  abstain  from  all  foolish  waste  of  it. 
I  will  each  day  spend,  set  in  motion,  put  into  action  only  as 
much  of  it  as  is  compatible  with  its  normal  duration,  and 
healthy  development.  By  an  unlimited  extension  of  the 
working  day,  you  may  in  one  day  use  up  a  quantity  of  labour- 
power  greater  than  I  can  restore  in  three.  What  you  gain  in 
labour  I  lose  in  substance.  The  use  of  my  labour-power  and 
the  spoliation  of  it  are  quite  different  things.  If  the  average 
time  that  (doing  a  reasonable  amount  of  work)  an  average 
labourer  can  live,  is  80  years,  the  value  of  my  labour-power, 
which  you  pay  me  from  c^ay  to  day  is  g—^  or  -^  of  its  total 
value.  But  if  you  consume  it  in  10  years,  you  pay  me  daily 
jjjgg-  instead  of  -—■  of  its  total  value,  i.e.,  only  J  of  its  daily 
value,  and  you  rob  me,  therefore,  every  day  of  f  of  the  value  of 
my  commodity.  You  pay  me  for  one  day's  labour-power, 
whilst  you  use  that  of  3  days.  That  is  against  our  contract 
and  the  law  of  exchanges.  I  demand,  therefore,  a  working 
day  of  normal  length,  and  I  demand  it  without  any  appeal  to 
your  heart,  for  in  money  matters  sentiment  is  out  of  place. 
You  may  be  a  model  citizen,  perhaps  a  member  of  the 
Society  for  the  Prevention  of  Cruelty  to  Animals,  and  in  the 
odour  of  sanctity  to  boot;  but  the  thing  that  you  represent  face 
to  face  with  me  has  no  heart  in  its  breast.  That  which  seems 
to  throb  there  is  my  own  heart-beating.     I  demand  the  normal 


2i8  Capitalist  Production. 

working  day  because  I,  like  every  other  seller,  demand   tlie 
value  of  my  commodity.  ^ 

We  see  then,  that,  apart  from  extremely  elastic  bounds,  the 
nature  of  the  exchange  of  commodities  itself  imposes  no  limit  to 
the  working  day,  no  limit  to  surplus-labour.  The  capitalist  main- 
tains his  rights  as  a  purchaser  when  he  tries  to  make  the  work- 
ing day  as  long  as  possible,  and  to  make,  whenever  possible,  two 
working  days  out  of  one.  On  the  other  hand,  the  j)ecu]iar 
nature  of  the  commodity  sold  implies  a  limit  to  its  consump- 
tion by  the  purchaser,  and  the  labourer  maintains  his  right 
as  seller  when  he  wishes  to  reduce  the  working  day  to  one  of 
definite  normal  duration.  There  is  here,  therefore,  an  anti- 
nomy, right  against  right,  both  equally  bearing  the  seal  of  the 
law  of  exchanges.  Between  equal  rights  force  decides.  Hence 
is  it  that  in  the  history  of  capitalist  production,  the  determin- 
ation of  what  is  a  working  day,  presents  itself  as  the  result  of 
a  struggle,  a  struggle  between  collective  capital,  i.e.,  the  class  of 
capitalists,  and  collective  labour  i.e.,  the  working  class. 

SECTION  2.  —THE  GREED  FOR  SURPLUS-LABOUR.    MANUFACTURER  AND  BOYARD. 

Capital  has  not  invented  surplus-labour.  Wherever  a  part 
of  society  possesses  the  monopoly  of  the  means  of  production,  the 
labourer,  free  or  not  free,  must  add  to  the  working  time 
necessary  for  his  own  maintenance  an  extra  working  time  in 
order  to  produce  the  means  of  subsistence  for  the  owners  of  the 
means  of  production,^  whether  this  proprietor  be  the  Athenian 
«ax«,-  KayuSo;,  Etruscau  tlicocrat,  civis  Romanus,  Norman  baron, 
American  slave  owner,  Wallachian  Boyard,  modern  landlord  or 
capitalist.^     It  is,  however,  clear  that  in  any  given  economic 

1  During  the  great  strike  of  the  London  builders,  1860-61,  for  the  reduction  of  the 
working  day  to  9  hours,  their  Commitlae  published  a  manifesto  that  contained,  to 
some  extent,  the  plea  of  our  worker.  The  manifesto  alludes,  not  without  irony,  to 
the  fact,  that  the  greatest  profit-monger  amongst  the  building  masters,  a  certain 
Sir  M.  Peto,  was  in  the  odour  of  sanctity.  (This  same  Peto,  after  1867,  came  to  an 
end  k  la  Strousberg.) 

2  "  Those  who  labour  ....  in  reality  feed  both  the  pensioners  .  .  .  [called 
the  rich]  and  themselves."    (Edmund  Burke,  1.  c,  p.  2.) 

•*  Niebuhr  in  his  "  Roman  History  "  says  very  naively  :  "It  is  evident  that  works 
like  the  Etruscan,  which  in  their  ruins  astound  us,  presuppose  in  little  (!)  states  lords 
and  vassals."  Sismondi  says  far  more  to  the  purpose  that  "Brussels  lace"  pre- 
supposes wage-lords  and  wage-slaves. 


The   Working  Day,  219 

formation  of  society,  where  not  the  exchange-value  but  the 
nse-vahie  of  the  product  predominates,  surplus-labour  will  be 
limited  by  a  given  set  of  wants  which  may  be  greater  or  less, 
and  that  here  no  boundless  thirst  for  surplus-labour  arises  from 
the  nature  of  the  production  itself  Hence  in  antiquity  over- 
work becomes  horrible  only  when  the  object  is  to  obtain  ex- 
change-value in  its  specific  independent  money-form  ;  in  the 
production  of  gold  and  silver.  Compulsory  working  to  death 
is  here  the  recognised  form  of  over-woik.  Only  read  Diodorus 
Siculus/  Still  these  are  exceptions  in  antiquity.  But  as  soon 
as  people,  whose  production  still  moves  within  the  lower  forms 
of  slave-labour,  corvee-labour,  &c.,  are  drawn  into  the  whirlpool 
of  an  international  market  dominated  by  the  capitalistic  mode 
of  production,  the  sale  of  their  products  for  export  becoming 
their  principal  interest,  the  civilized  horrors  of  over-work  are 
grafted  on  the  barbaric  horrors  of  slavery,  serfdom,  &;c.  Hence 
the  negro  labour  in  the  Southern  States  of  the  American  Union 
preserved  something  of  a  patriarchal  character,  so  long  as  pro- 
duction was  chiefly  directed  to  immediate  local  consumption. 
But  in  proportion,  as  the  export  of  cotton  became  of  vital 
interest  to  these  states,  the  over- working  of  the  negro  and  some- 
times the  using  up  of  his  life  in  7  years  of  labour  became  a 
factor  in  a  calculated  and  calculating  system.  It  was  no  longer 
a  question  of  obtaining  from  him  a  certain  quantity  of  useful 
products.  It  was  now  a  question  of  production  of  surplus- 
labour  itself  So  was  it  also  wdth  the  corvee,  e.g.^  in  the 
Danubian  Principalities  (now  Roumania). 

The  comparison  of  the  greed  for  surplus-labour  in  the 
Danubian  Principalities  with  the  same  greed  in  English  factories 
has  a  special  interest,  because  surplus-labour  in  the  corvee  has 
an  independent  and  palpable  form. 

Suppose  the  working  day  consists  of  6  hours  of  necessary 
labour,  and  6  hours  of  surplus-labour.     Then  the  free  labourer 

1  "  One  cannot  see  these  unfortunates  (in  the  gold  mines  between  Egypt,  Ethiopia, 
and  Arabia)  who  cannot  even  have  their  bodies  clean,  or  their  nakedness  clothed, 
without  pitying  their  miserable  lot.  There  is  no  indulgence,  no  forbearance  for  the 
sick,  the  feeble,  the  aged,  for  woman's  weakness.  All  must,  forced  by  blows,  work 
on  until  death  puts  an  end  to  their  sufferings  and  their  distress."  (**  Diod.  Sic.  Bibl. 
Hist.,"  lib.  3,  c.  13.) 


2  20  Capitalist  ProduclioJl. 

gives  the  capitalist  every  week  6  X  6  or  36  hours  of  surplus- 
labour.  It  is  the  same  as  if  he  worked  3  days  in  the  week  for 
himself,  and  3  days  in  the  week  gratis  for  the  capitalist.  But 
this  is  not  evident  on  the  surface.  Surplus-labour  and  necessary 
labour  glide  one  into  the  other.  I  can,  therefore,  express  the 
same  relationship  b}^  saying,  e.g.,  that  the  labourer  in  every 
minute  works  30  seconds  for  himself,  and  30  for  the  capitalist, 
etc.  It  is  otherwise  with  the  corvee.  The  necessary  labour 
which  the  Wallachian  peasant  does  for  his  own  maintenance  is 
distinctly  marked  off  from  his  surplus-labour  on  behalf  of  the 
Boyard.  The  one  he  does  on  his  own  field,  the  other  on  the 
seignorial  estate.  Both  parts  of  the  labour- time  exist,  there- 
fore, independently,  side  by  side  one  with  the  other.  In  the 
corvee  the  surplus-labour  is  accurately  marked  off  from  the 
necessary  labour.  This,  however,  can  make  no  difference  with 
regard  to  the  quantitative  relation  of  surplus-labour  to  necessary 
labour.  Three  days'  surplus-labour  in  the  week  remain  three 
days  that  yield  no  equivalent  to  the  labourer  himself,  whether 
it  be  called  corvde  or  wage-labour.  But  in  the  capitalist  the 
greed  for  surplus-labour  appears  in  the  straining  after  an  un- 
limited extension  of  the  working  day,  in  the  Boyard  more 
simply  in  a  direct  hunting  after  days  of  corvde.^ 

In  the  Danubian  Principalities  the  corvee  was  mixed  up  with 
rents  in  kind  and  other  appurtenances  of  bondage,  but  it  formed 
the  most  important  tribute  paid  to  the  ruling  class.  Where 
this  was  the  case,  the  coi'v^e  rarely  arose  from  serfdom  ;  serfdom 
much  more  frequently  on  the  other  hand  took  origin  from  the 
corv^e.^     This  is  what  took  place  in  the  Roumanian  provinces. 

1  That  which  follows  refers  to  the  situation  in  the  Roumanian  provinces  before  the 
change  effected  since  the  Crimean  war. 

2  This  holds  likewise  for  Germany,  and  especially  for  Prussia  east  of  the  Elbe.  In 
the  15th  century  the  German  peasant  was  nearly  everywhere  a  man,  who,  whilst 
subject  to  certain  rents  paid  in  produce  and  labour  was  otherwise  at  least 
practically  free.  The  German  colonists  in  Brandenburg,  Pomerania,  Silesia,  and 
Eastern  Prussia,  were  even  legally  acknowledged  as  free  men.  The  victory  of  the 
nobility  in  the  peasants'  war  put  an  end  to  that.  Not  only  were  the  conquered  South 
German  peasants  again  enslaved.  From  the  middle  of  the  16th  century  the  peasants 
of  Eastern  Prussia,  Brandenburg,  Pomerania,  and  Silesia,  and  soon  after  the  free 
peasants  of  Schleswig-Holstein  were  degraded  to  the  condition  of  serfs.  (Maurer, 
Fronhofe  iv.  vol  , — Meitzen,  der  Boden  des  preussischen  Staats. — Hansen, 
Leibeigenschaft  in  Schleswig-Holstein. — Ed.) 


The   Working  Day,  221 

Their  original  mode  c£  production  was  based  on  community  of 
the  soil,  but  not  in  the  Slavonic  or  Indian  form.  Part  of  the 
land  was  cultivated  in  severalty  as  freehold  by  the  members  of 
the  community,  another  part — ager  puhlicus — was  cultivated 
by  them  in  common.  The  products  of  this  common  labour 
served  partly  as  a  reserve  fund  against  bad  harvests  and  other 
accidents,  partly  as  a  public  store  for  providing  the  costs  of 
war,  religion,  and  other  common  expenses.  In  course  of  time 
military  and  clerical  dignitaries  usurped,  along  with  the  com- 
mon land,  the  labour  spent  upon  it.  The  labour  of  the  free 
peasants  on  their  common  land  was  transformed  into  corvee  for 
the  thieves  of  the  common  land.  This  corvee  soon  developed 
into  a  servile  relationship  existing  in  point  of  fact,  not  in  point 
of  law,  until  Russia,  the  liberator  of  the  world,  made  it  legal 
under  pretence  of  abolishing  serfdom.  The  code  of  the  corvee, 
Avhich  the  Russian  General  KisselefF  proclaimed  in  1831,  was  of 
course  dictated  by  the  Boyards  themselves.  Thus  Russia  con- 
quered  with  one  blow  the  magnates  of  the  Danubian  provinces, 
and  the  applause  of  liberal  cretins  throughout  Europe. 

According  to  the  "  Reglement  organique,"  as  this  code  of  the 
corvee  is  called,  every  Wallachian  peasant  owes  to  the  so-called 
landlord,  besides  a  mass  of  detailed  payments  in  kind :  (1),  12 
days  of  general  labour ;  (2),  one  day  of  field  labour ;  (3),  one 
day  of  wood  carrying.  In  all,  14  days  in  the  year.  With  deep 
insight  into  political  economy,  however,  the  working  day  is  not 
taken  in  its  ordinary  sense,  but  as  the  working  day  necessary 
to  the  production  of  an  average  daily  product ;  and  that  average 
daily  product  is  determined  in  so  crafty  a  way  that  no  Cyclops 
would  be  done  with  it  in  24  hours.  In  dry  words,  the  Regle- 
ment itself  declares  with  true  Russian  irony  that  by  12  working 
days  one  must  understand  the  product  of  the  manual  labour  of 
36  days,  by  1  day  of  field  labour  3  days,  and  by  1  day  of  wood 
carrying  in  like  manner  three  times  as  much.  In  all,  42 
corvee  days.  To  this  had  to  be  added  the  so-called  jobagie, 
service  due  to  the  lord  for  extraordinary  occasions.  In  propor- 
tion to  the  size  of  its  population,  every  village  has  to  furnish 
annually  a  definite  contingent  to  the  jobagie.  This  additional 
corvee  is  estimated  at  14  days  for  each  Wallachian  peasant 


22  2  Capitalist  Production. 

Thus  the  prescribed  corvee  amounts  to  56  working  days  yearly. 
Ijut  the  agricultural  year  in  Wallachia  numbers  in  consequence 
of  the  severe  climate  only  210  days,  of  which  40  for  Sundays 
and  holidays,  30  on  an  average  for  bad  weather,  together  70 
days,  do  not  count.  1-10  working  days  remain.  The  ratio  of 
the  corvee  to  the  necessary  labour  g-  or  ^Qi  |  7o  gives  a  much 
smaller  rate  of  surplus-value  than  that  which  regulates  the 
labour  of  the  English  agricultural  or  factory  labourer.  This 
is,  however,  only  the  legally  prescribed  corvee.  And  in  a  spirit 
yet  more  "  liberal  "  than  the  English  Factory  Acts,  the  "  Kegle- 
ment  organique  "  has  known  how  to  facilitate  its  own  evasion. 
After  it  has  made  h^  days  out  of  12,  the  nominal  days  work  of 
each  of  the  o^  corvee  days  is  again  so  arranged  that  a  portion 
of  it  must  fall  on  the  ensuing  day.  In  one  day,  e.g.,  must  be 
weeded  an  extent  of  land,  which,  for  this  work,  especially  in 
maize  plantations,  needs  twice  as  much  time.  The  legal  da3^'s 
work  for  some  kinds  of  agricultural  labour  is  interpretable  in 
such  a  way  that  the  day  begins  in  May  and  ends  in  October. 
\vi  Moldavia  conditions  are  still  harder.  "  The  12  corvee  days 
of  the  '  K^glement  organique '  cried  a  Boyard  drunk  with 
victory,  amount  to  3G5  days  in  the  year."^ 

If  the  Reglement  organique  of  the  Danubian  provinces  was 
a  positive  expression  of  the  greed  for  surplus-labour  which 
every  paragraph  legalised,  the  English  Factory  Acts  are  the 
negative  expression  of  the  same  greed.  These  acts  curb  the 
passion  of  capital  for  a  limitless  draining  of  labour-power,  by 
forcibly  limiting  the  working  day  by  state  regulations,  made 
by  a  state  tliat  is  ruled  by  capitalist  and  landlord.  Apart  from 
the  working-class  movement  that  daily  grew  more  threatening, 
the  limiting  of  factory  labour  was  dictated  by  the  same  necessity 
which  spread  guano  over  the  English  fields.  The  same  blind 
eagerness  for  plunder  that  in  the  one  case  exhausted  the  soil, 
had,  in  the  other,  torn  up  by  the  roots  the  living  force  of  the 
nation.  Periodical  epidemics  speak  on  this  point  as  clearly  as 
the  diminishing  military  standard  in  Germany  and  France.^ 

1  Further  details  are  to  be  found  in  E.  Regnault's  "  Histoire  politique  et  sociale  des 
Principautes  Danubiennes       Pai  is,  1855 

2  "In  general  and  within  certain  limits,  exceeding  the  medium  size  of  their  kind,  is 
evidence  of  the  prosperity  of  organic  beings.     As  to  man,  his  bodily  height  lessens  if 


The   Working  Day.  223 

The  Factory  Act  of  1850  now  in  force  (1867)  allows  for  the 
average  working-day  10  hours,  \.e.,  for  the  first  5  days  12  hours 
from  6  a.m.  to  6  p.m.,  including  \  an  hour  for  breakfast,  and 
an  hour  for  dinner,  and  thus  leaving  lOJ  working  hours,  and 
8  hours  for  Saturday,  from  6  a.m.  to  2  p.m.,  of  which  \  an  hour 
is  subtracted  for  breakfast.  60  working  hours  are  left,  lOJ  for 
each  of  the  first  5  days,  TA  for  the  last.^  Certain  guardians  of 
these  laws  are  appointed,  Factory  Inspectors,  directly  under  the 
Home  Secretary,  whose  reports  are  published  lialf-y early,  by 
order  of  Parliament.  They  give  regular  and  ofiicial  statistics  of 
the  capitalistic  greed  for  surplus-labour. 

Let  us  listen,  for  a  moment,  to  the  Factory  Inspectors.^ 
"  The  fraudulent  millowner  begins  work  a  quarter  of  an  hour 
(sometimes  more,  sometimes  less)  before  6  a.m.,  and  leaves  ofi:' 
a  quarter  of  an  hour  (sometimes  more,  sometimes  less)  after 
6  p.m.     He  takes  5  minutes  from  the  beginning  and  from  the 

1  is  due  growth  is  interfered  with,  either  by  physical  or  social  conditions.  In  all 
European  countries  in  which  the  conscription  holds,  since  its  introduction,  the  medium 
height  of  adult  men,  and  generally  their  fitness  for  military  service,  has  diminished. 
Before  the  revolution  (1789),  the  minimum  for  the  infantry  in  France  was  165  centi- 
metres ;  in  1818  (law  of  March  10th),  157;  by  the  law  of  1852,  156  cm.  ;  on  the 
average  in  France  more  than  half  are  rejected  on  account  of  deficient  height  or  bodily 
weakness.  The  military  standard  in  Saxony  was  in  1780,  178  cm.  It  is  now  155. 
In  Prussia  it  is  157.  According  to  the  statement  of  Dr.  Meyer  in  the  Bavarian 
Gazette,  May  9th,  1862,  the  result  of  an  average  of  9  years  is,  that  in  Prussia  out  of 
1000  conscripts  716  were  unfit  for  military  service,  317  because  of  deficiency  in  height, 
and  399  because  of  bodily  defects.  .  .  .  Berlin  in  1858  could  not  provide  its  con- 
tingent of  recruits  ;  it  was  156  men  short."  J.  von  Liebig :  "Die  Chemie  in  ihrer 
Anwendung  auf  Agrikultur  und  Physiologic,  1863,'  7th  Ed.,  vol.  1.,  pp.  117,  118. 

1  The  history  of  the  Factory  Act  of  1850  will  be  found  in  the  course  of  this  chapter. 

2  I  only  touch  here  and  there  on  the  period  from  the  beginning  of  modern  industry 
in  England  to  1845.  For  this  period  I  refer  the  reader  to  "  Die  Lage  der  arbei- 
tenden  Klasse  in  England,  von  Fried  ich  Engels,  Leipzig,  1845."  How  completely 
Engels  understood  the  nature  of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production  is  shown  by  the 
Factory  Reports,  Reports  on  Mines,  &c,  that  have  appeared  since  1845,  and  how 
wonderfully  he  painted  the  circumstances  in  detail  is  seen  on  the  most  sui>erficial 
comparison  of  his  work  with  the  official  reports  of  the  Children's  Employment  Com- 
mission, published  18  to  10  years  later  (1863- 1867).  ''  hese  deal  especially  with  the 
branches  of  industry  in  which  the  Factory  Acts  had  not,  up  to  186:^,  been  introduced, 
in  fact  are  not  yet  introduced.  Here,  then,  little  or  no  alteration  had  been  enforced, 
by  authority,  in  the  conditions  painted  by  Engels.  I  borrow  my  examples  chiefly 
from  the  free  trade  period  after  1848,  that  age  of  paradise,  of  which  the  commercial 
travellers  for  the  great  firm  of  free  trade,  blatant  as  ignorant,  tell  such  fabulous  tales. 
For  the  rest  England  figures  here  in  the  foreground  because  she  is  the  classic  rejire- 
sentative  of  capitalist  production,  and  she  alone  has  a  continuous  set  of  official 
statistics  of  the  things  we  are  considering. 


2  24  Capitalist  Prodiution. 

end  of  the  half  hour  nominally  allowed  for  breakfast,  and  10 
mirmtes  at  the  beginning  and  end  of  the  hour  nominally  allowed 
for  dinner.  He  works  for  a  quarter  of  an  hour  (sometimes 
more,  sometimes  less)  after  2  p.m.  on  Saturday.  Thus  his  gain 
is — 

Before  6  a.m.,...  ...  ...  15  minutes. 

After  6  p.m.,  ...  ...  ...  15         „ 

At  breakfast  time,  ..  ...  10         „ 

At  dinner  time,  ...  ...  20         „ 

00 
Five  daj's — 300  minutes. 
On  Saturday  before  6  a.m.  ...  15  minutes. 

At  breakfast  time,         ...  ...  10         „ 

After  2  p.m.,  ...  ...  ...  15         „ 


40  minutes.    . 
Total  weekly,  ...  ...  340  minutes. 

Or  5  hours  and  40  minutes  weekly,  which  multiplied  by  50 
working  weeks  in  the  year  (allowing  two  for  holidays  and 
occasional  stoppages)  is  equal  to  27  working  days."^ 

"Five  minutes  a  day's  increased  work,  multiplied  by  weeks, 
are  equal  to  two  and  a  half  days  of  produce  in  the  year."^ 

"  An  additional  hour  a  day  gained  by  small  instalments  before 
6  a.m.,  after  6  p.m.,  and  at  the  beginning  and  end  of  the  times 
nominally  fixed  for  meals,  is  nearly  equivalent  to  working  13 
months  in  the  year."^ 

Crises  during  which  production  is  interrupted  and  the  fac- 
tories work  "  short  time,"  i.e.^  for  only  a  part  of  the  week, 
naturally  do  not  affect  the  tendency  to  extend  the  working 
day.  The  less  business  there  is,  the  more  profit  has  to  be  made 
on  the  business  done.  The  less  time  spent  in  work,  the  more 
of  that  time  has  to  be  turned  into  surplus  labour-time. 

1  Suggestions,  &c.  by  Mr.  L.  Horner,  Inspector  of  Factories,  in :  Factory  Regula- 
tions Act.  Ordered  by  the  House  of  Commons  to  be  printed,  9th  August,  1859,  p. 
4,5. 

2  E-epotts  of  the  Inspector  of  Factories  for  the  half  year,  October,  1856,  p.  35. 

3  Reports,  &c.,  30tli  April,  1858,  p.  9. 


The   Working  Day.  225 

Thus  the  Factory  Inspector's  report  on  the  period  of  the 
crisis  from  1857  to  1858  : 

"  It  may  seem  inconsistent  that  there  should  be  any  over- 
working at  a  time  when  trade  is  so  bad  ;  but  that  very  bad- 
ness leads  to  the  transgression  by  unscrupulous  men,  they  get 

the  extra  profit  of  it In  the  last  half  year,  says  Leonard 

Horner,  122  mills  in  my  district  have  been  given  up ;  143  were 
found  standing,"  yet,  overwork  is  continued  beyond  the  legal 
hours.^ 

"  For  a  great  part  of  the  time,"  says  Mr.  Howell,  "owing  to  the 
depression  of  trade,  many  factories  were  altogether  closed,  and  a 
still  greater  number  were  working  short  time.  I  continue,  how- 
ever, to  receive  about  the  usual  number  of  complaints  that  half, 
or  three-quarters  of  an  hour  in  the  day,  are  snatched  from  the 
workers  by  encroaching  upon  the  times  professedly  allowed  for 
rest  and  refreshment."^  The  same  phenomenon  was  reproduced 
on  a  smaller  scale  during  the  frightful  cotton-crisis  from  1861 
to  1865.^  "  It  is  sometimes  advanced  by  way  of  excuse,  when 
persons  are  found  at  work  in  a  factory,  either  at  a  meal  hour, 
or  at  some  illegal  time,  that  they  will  not  leave  the  mill  at  the 
appointed  hour,  and  that  compulsion  is  necessary  to  force  them 
to  cease  work  [cleaning  their  machinery,  &c.],  especially  on 
Saturday  afternoons.  But,  if  the  hands  remain  in  a  factory 
after  the  machinery  has  ceased  to  revolve  .  .  .  they  would  not 
have  been  so  employed  if  sufiicient  time  had  been  set  apart 
specially  for  cleaning,  fee,  either  before  6  a.m.  [sic.^]  or  before 
2  p.m.  on  Saturday  afternoons."'^ 

1  Eeports,  &c.,  1.  e.,  p.  43. 

2  Reports,  &c.,  1.  c,  p.  25. 

3  Reports,  &c.  for  the  half  year  ending  30th  April,  1861.  See  Appendix  No.  2 ;  Re- 
ports, &c.,  31st  October,  1862,  p.  7,  52,  53.  The  violations  of  the  Acts  became  more 
numerous  during  the  last  half  year  ].863.  Cf.  Reports,  &c.,  ending  31st  October, 
1863,  p.  7. 

4  Reports,  &c.,  October  31st,  1860,  p.  23.  With  what  fanaticism,  according  to  the 
evidence  of  manufacturers  given  in  courts  of  law,  their  hands  set  themselves  against 
every  interruption  in  factory  labour,  the  following  curious  circumstance  shows.  In  the 
beginning  of  June,  1836,  information  reached  the  magistrates  of  Dewsbury  (York- 
shire) that  the  owners  of  8  large  mills  in  the  neighbourhood  of  Batley  had  violated  the 
Factory  Acts.  Some  of  these  gf  ntlemen  were  accused  of  having  kept  at  work  5  boys 
between  12  and  15  years  of  age,  from  6  a.m.  on  Friday  to  4  p.m.  on  the  following 
Saturday,  not  allowing  them  any  respite  except  for  meals  and  one  hour  for  sleep  at 
midnight.     And  these  children  had  to  do  this  ceaseless  labour  of  30  hours  in  the 


226  Capitalist  Production. 

"  The  profit  to  be  gained  by  it  (over-working  in  violation  of 
the  Act)  appears  to  be,  to  many,  a  greater  temptation  than  they 
can  resist ;  they  calculate  upon  the  chance  of  not  being  found 
out ;  and  v^^hen  they  see  the  small  amount  of  penalty  and  costs, 
which  those  who  have  been  convicted  have  had  to  pay,  they 
find  that  if  they  should  be  detected  there  will  still  be  a  con- 
siderable balance  of  gain.  .  .  }  In  cases  where  the  additional 
time  is  gained  by  a  multiplication  of  small  thefts  in  the  course 
of  the  day,  there  are  insuperable  difiiculties  to  the  inspectors 
making  out  a  case."^ 

These  "  small  thefts  "  of  capital  from  the  labourer's  meal  and 
recreation  time,  the  factory  inspectors  also  designate  as  "  petty 
pilferings  of  minutes,"^  "  snatching  a  few  minutes,'"*  or,  as  the 
labourers  technically  called  them,  "  nibbling  and  cribbling  at 
meal  times."  ® 

It  is  evident  that  in  this  atmosphere  the  formation  of  surplus- 
value  by  surplus-labour,  is  no  secret.  "  If  you  allow  me,"  said 
a  highly  respectable  master  to  me,  "  to  work  only  ten  minutes 
in  the  da}^  over-time,  you  put  one  thousand  a"  year  in  my 
pocket."^     "  Moments  are  the  elements  of  profit."  ^ 

Nothing  is  from  this  point  of  view  more  characteristic  than 
the  designation  of  the  workers  who  work  full  time  as  "  full- 
timers,"  and  the  children  under  13  who  are  only  allowed  to 
work  6  hours  as  "  half-timers."  The  worker  is  here  nothing 
more  than  perfconified  labour-time.  All  individual  distinctions 
are  merged  in  those  of  "full-timers  "  and  "  half-timers."^ 

"  shoddy-hole,"  as  the  hole  is  called,  in  which  the  woollen  rags  are  pulled  in  pieces, 
and  where  a  dense  atmosphere  of  dust,  shreds,  &c.,  forces  even  the  adult  workman  to 
cover  his  mouth  continually  with  handkerchiefs  for  the  protection  of  his  lungs  !  The 
accused  gentlemen  affirm  in  lieu  of  taking  an  oath — as  quakers  they  were  too  scrupu- 
lously religious  to  take  an  oath — that  they  had,  in  their  great  compassion  for  the 
unhappy  children,  allowed  them  four  hours  for  sleep,  but  the  obstinate  cliildren 
absolutely  would  not  go  to  bed.  The  quaker  gentlemen  were  mulcted  in  £20.  Dry- 
den  anticipated  these  gentry : 

"  Fox  full  fraught  in  seeming  sanctity, 
That  feared  an  oath,  but  like  the  devil  would  lie, 
That  look'd  like  Lent,  and  had  the  holy  leer, 
And  durst  not  sin  !  before  he  said  his  prayer  ! " 

1  Rep.,  31st  Oct.,  1856,  p.  34.  3  i.  c,  p.  48.  M.  c,  p.  48. 

2  1.  c,  p.  35.  4 1.  c.,  p.  48.  6  1.  c,  p.  48. 
1  Report  of  the  Insp.  &c.,  30th  April,  1860,  p.  56. 

8  This  is  the  official  expression  both  in  the  factories  and  in  the  reports. 


The   Working  Day,  227 

SECTION   3. — BRANCHES   OF   ENGLISH   INDUSTRY   WITHOUT   LEGAL   LIMITS   TO 

EXPLOITATION. 

We  have  hitherto  considered  the  tendency  to  the  extension  of 
the  working  day,  the  were-wolf's  hanger  for  surplus-labour  in 
a  department  where  the  monstrous  exactions,  not  surpassed, 
says  an  English  bourgeois  economist,  by  the  cruelties  of  the 
Spaniards  to  the  American  red-skins,^  caused  capital  at  last  to 
be  bound  by  the  chains  of  legal  regulations.  Now,  let  us  cast 
a  glance  at  certain  branches  of  production  in  which  the  exploita- 
tion of  labour  is  either  free  from  fetters  to  this  day,  or  was  so 
yesterda}^ 

Mr.  Broughton  Charlton,  county  magistrate,  declared,  as 
chairman  of  a  meeting  held  at  the  Assembly  Rooms,  Nottingham, 
on  the  14th  January,  1860,  "that  there  was  an  amount  of 
privation  and  suffering  among  that  portion  of  the  population 
connected  with  the  lace  trade,  unknown  in  other  parts  of  the 
kingdom,  indeed,  in  the  civilized  world  .  .  .  Children  of 
nine  or  ten  years  are  dragged  from  their  squalid  beds  at  two, 
three,  or  four  o'clock  in  the  morning  and  compelled  to  work  for 
a  bare  subsistence  until  ten,  eleven,  or  twelve  at  night,  their 
limbs  wearing  away,  their  frames  dwindling,  their  faces  whiten- 
ing, and  their  humanity  absolutely  sinking  into  a  stone-like 

torpor,  utterly  horrible  to  contemplate We  are  rot 

surprised  that  Mr.  Mallett,  or  any  other  manufacturer,  should 

stand   forward   and   protest   against   discussion The 

system,  as  the  Rev.  Montagu  Valpy  describes  it,  is  one  of 
unmitigated  slavery,  socially,  physically,  morally,  and  spiritually. 
....  What  can  be  thought  of  a  town  which  holds  a  public 
meeting  to  petition  that  the  period  of  labour  for  men  shall  be 

diminished    to    eighteen    hours   a   day  ? We   declaim 

against  the  Virginian  and  Carolinian  cotton-planters.     Is  their 

1  "  The  cupidity  of  mill-owners  whose  cruelties  in  the  pursuit  of  gain  have  hardly- 
been  exceeded  by  those  perpetrated  by  the  Spaniards  on  the  conquest  of  America  in 
the  pursuit  of  gold."  John  Wade,  History  of  the  Middle  and  Working  Classes,  3rd 
Ed.  London,  1835,  p.  114.  The  theoretical  part  of  this  book,  a  kind  of  hand-book  of 
Political  Economy,  is,  considering  the  time  of  its  publication,  original  in  some  parts, 
c.r/.,  on  commercial  crises.  The  historical  part  is,  to  a  great  extent,  a  shameless 
plagiarism  of  Sir  F.  M.  Eden's  **  History  of  the  Poor,"  London,  1799, 


2  28  Capitalist  Production, 

black-market,  their  lash,  and  their  barter  of  human  flesh  more 
detestable  than  this  slow  sacrifice  of  humanity  which  takes 
place  in  order  that  veils  and  collars  may  be  fabricated  for  the 
benefit  of  capitalists  ? "  ^ 

The  potteries  of  Staffordshire  have,  during  the  last  22  years, 
been  the  subject  of  three  parliamentary  inquiries.  The  result  is 
embodied  in  Mr.  Scriven's  Report  of  ]841  to  the  "Children's 
Employment  Commissioners,"  in  the  leport  of  Dr.  Greenhow 
of  1860  published  by  order  of  the  medical  officer  of  the  Privy 
Council  (Public  Health,  3rd  Report,  112-113),  lastly,  in  the 
report  of  Mr.  Longe  of  1862  in  the  "First  Report  of  the 
Children's  Employment  Commission,  of  the  13th  June,  18G3." 
For  my  purpose  it  is  enough  to  take,  from  the  reports  of  1860 
and  1863,  some  depositions  of  the  exploited  children  themselves. 
From  the  children  we  may  form  an  opinion  as  to  the  adults, 
especially  the  girls  and  women,  and  that  in  a  branch  of  industry 
by  the  side  of  which  cotton-spinning  appears  an  agreeable  and 
healthful  occupation.  ^ 

William  Wood,  9  years  old,  was  7  years  and  10  months  when 
he  began  to  work.  He  "  ran  moulds  "  (carried  ready-moulded 
articles  into  the  drying  room,  afterwards  bringing  back  tlie 
em];)ty  mould)  from  the  beginning.  He  came  to  work  every  day 
in  the  week  at  6  a.m.,  and  left  off  about  9  p.m.  "  I  work  till 
9  o'clock  at  night  six  days  in  the  week.  I  have  done  so  seven 
or  eight  weeks."  Fifteen  hours  of  labour  for  a  child  7  years 
old  !  J.  Murray,  12  years  of  age,  says :  "  I  turn  jigger,  and  run 
moulds.  I  come  at  6.  Sometimes  I  come  at  4.  I  worked  all 
night  last  night,  till  6  o'clock  this  morning.  I  have  not  been 
in  bed  since  the  night  before  last.  There  were  eight  or  nine 
other  boys  working  last  night.  All  but  one  have  come  this 
morning.  I  get  3  shillings  and  sixpence.  I  do  not  get  any  more 
for  working  at  night.  I  worked  two  nights  last  week."  Fern^^- 
hough,  a  boy  of  ten  :  "  I  have  not  always  an  hour  (for  dinner). 
I  have  only  half  an  hour  sometimes  ;  on  Thursday,  Friday,  and 
Saturday."  ^ 

1  "  Daily  Telegraph,"  17th  January,  1860. 

2  Cf.  F.  Engels'  Lage,  etc.,  p.  249-51. 

3  Children's  Employment  Commission.     First  report,  etc.,  1863.     Evidence,  p.  10, 
19,  18. 


The   Working  Day,  229 

Dr.  Greenhow  states  that  the  average  duration  of  life  in  the 
pottery  districts  of  Stoke-on-Trent,  and  Wolstanton  is  ex- 
traordinarily short.  Although  in  the  district  of  Stoke,  only 
36'6%  and  in  Wolstanton  only  30-47o  of  the  adult  male 
population  above  20  are  employed  in  the  potteries,  among  the 
men  of  that  age  in  the  first  district  more  than  half,  in  the 
second,  nearly  |  of  the  whole  deaths  are  the  result  of  pulmonary 
diseases  among  the  potters.  Dr.  Boothroyd,  a  medical  practitioner 
at  Hanley,  says  :  "  Each  successive  generation  of  potters  is  more 
dwarfed  and  less  robust  than  the  preceding  one.''  In  like 
manner  another  doctor,  Mr.  M'Bean:  "Since  he  began  to  practise 
among  the  potters  25  years  ago,  he  had  observed  a  marked 
degeneration  especially  shown  in  diminution  of  stature  and 
breadth."  These  statements  are  taken  from  the  report  of  Dr. 
Greenhow  in  1860. 

From  the  report  of  the  Commissioners  in  1863,  the  following : 
Dr.  J.  T.  Arledge,  senior  physician  of  the  North  Staffordshire 
Infirmary,  says  :  "  The  potters  as  a  class,  both  men  and  women, 
represent  a  degenerated  population,  both  physically  and  morally. 
They  are,  as  a  rule,  stunted  in  growth,  ill-shaped,  and  frequently 
ill-formed  in  the  chest ;  they  become  prematurely  old,  and  are 
certainly  short-lived ;  they  are  phlegmatic  and  bloodless,  and 
exhibit  their  debility  of  constitution  by  obstinate  attacks  of 
dyspepsia,  and  disorders  of  the  liver  and  kidneys,  and  by 
i-heumatism.  But  of  all  diseases  they  are  especially  prone  to 
chest-disease,  to  pneumonia,  phthisis,  bronchitis,  and  asthma. 
One  form  would  appear  peculiar  to  them,  and  is  known  as 
potter's  asthma,  or  potter's  consumption.  Scrofula  attacking 
the  glands,  or  bones,  or  other  parts  of  the  body,  is  a  disease  of 

two-thirds  or  more  of  the  potters That  the  '  degener- 

escence '  of  the  population  of  this  district  is  not  even  greater 
than  it  is,  is  due  to  the  constant  recruiting  from  the  adjacent 
country,  and  intermarriages  with  more  healthy  races."  ^ 

Mr.  Charles  Parsons, late  house  surgeon  of  the  same  institution, 
writes  in  a  letter  to  Commissioner  Longe,  amongst  other  things : 
"  I  can  only  speak  from  personal  observation  and  not  from 

1  Public  Health,  3rd  report,  etc.,  p.  102,  104,  105. 

2  ChUd.  Emnl.  Comra.  I.  Report,  p.  24. 


230  Capitalist  Production. 

statistical  data,  but  I  do  not  hesitate  to  assert  that  my  indigna- 
tion has  been  aroused  again  and  again  at  the  sight  of  poor 
children  whose  health  has  been  sacrificed  to  gratify  the  avarice 
of  either  parents  or  employers."  He  enumerates  the  causes 
of  tlie  diseases  of  the  potters,  and  sums  them  up  in  the  phrase, 
"  long  hours."  The  report  of  the  Commission  trusts  that  '*  a 
manufacture  which  has  assumed  so  prominent  a  place  in  the 
whole  world,  will  not  long  be  subject  to  the  remark  that  its 
great  success  is  accompanied  with  the  physical  deterioration, 
wide-spread  bodily  suffering,  and  early  death  of  the  workpeople 
.  .  by  whose  labour  and  skill  such  great  results  have  been 
achieved."  ^  And  all  that  holds  of  the  potteries  in  England  is 
true  of  those  in  Scotland. 

The  manufacture  of  lucifer  matches  dates  from  1833,  from 
the  discovery  of  the  method  of  applying  phosphorus  to  the 
match  itself.  Since  1845  this  manufacture  has  rapidly  devel- 
oped in  England,  and  has  extended  especially  amongst  the 
thickly  populated  parts  of  London  as  well  as  in  Manchester, 
Birmingham,  Liverpool,  Bristol,  Norwich,  Newcastle  and  Glas- 
gow. With  it  has  spread  the  form  of  lockjaw,  which  a  Vienna 
physician  in  1845  discovered  to  be  a  disease  peculiar  to 
lucifer-matchmakers.  Half  the  workers  are  children  under 
thirteen,  and  young  persons  under  eighteen.  The  manufacture 
is  on  account  of  its  unhealthiness  and  unpleasantness  in  such 
bad  odour  that  only  the  most  miserable  part  of  the  labouring 
class,  half-starved  widows  and  so  forth,  deliver  up  their 
children  to  it,  "  the  ragged,  half-starved,  untaught  children."-^ 

Of  the  witnesses  that  Commissioner  White  examined  (1863), 
270  were  under  18,  50  under  10,  10  only  8,  and  5  only  6  years 
old.  A  range  of  the  working  day  from  12  to  14  or  15  hours, 
night-labour,  irregular  meal  times,  meals  for  the  most  part 
taken  in  the  very  workrooms  that  are  pestilent  with  phos- 
phorus. Dante  would  have  found  the  worst  horrors  of  his 
Inferno  surpassed  in  this  manufacture. 

In  the  manufacture  of  paper-hangings  the  coarser  sorts  are 
printed  by  machine  ;  the  finer  by  hand  (block-printing).     Thft 

1  Children's  Employment  Commission,  p.  22,  and  xi. 

2  1.  c.  p.  xlvii. 
*  I.e.  p.  liv. 


The   Working  Day.  231 

most  active  business  months  are  from  the  beginning  of  October 
to  the  end  of  i.pril.  During  this  time  the  work  goes  on  fast 
and  furious  without  intermission  from  G  a.m.  to  10  p.m.  or 
further  into  the  night. 

J.  Leach  deposes :  "  Last  winter  six  out  of  nineteen  girls 
were  away  from  ill-health  at  one  time  from  over- work.  I  have 
to  bawl  at  them  to  keep  them  awake,"  W.  Duify  :  "  I  have 
seen  when  the  children  could  none  of  them  keep  their  eyes 
open  for  the  work;  indeed,  none  of  us  could."  J.  Lightbourne: 
"  Am  13  .  .  .  We  worked  last  winter  till  9  (evening),  and  the 
winter  before  till  10.  I  used  to  cry  with  sore  feet  every  night 
last  winter.  G.  Apsden :  "  That  boy  of  mine  .  .  .  when  he 
was  7  years  old  I  used  to  carry  him  on  my  back  to  and  fro 
through  the  snow,  and  he  used  to  have  16  hours  a  day  ...  I 
have  often  knelt  down  to  feed  him  as  he  stood  by  the  machine, 
for  he  could  not  leave  it  or  stop."  Smith,  the  managing 
partner  of  a  Manchester  factory  :  "  We  (he  means  his  "  hands  " 
who  work  for  "  us  ")  work  on,  with  no  stoppage  for  meals,  so 
that  the  day's  work  of  lOJ  hours  is  finished  by  4.30.  p.m.,  and 
all  after  that  is  overtime."  ^  (Does  this  Mr.  Smith  take  no 
meals  himself  during  10\  hours  ? )  *'  We  (this  same  Smith)  sel- 
dom leave  off  working  before  6  p.m.  (he  means  leave  off  the 
consumption  of  'our'  labour-power  machines),  so  that  we 
(iterum  Crispinus)  are  really  working  overtime  the  whole  year 

round For  all  these,  children  and  adults  alike  (152 

children  and  young  persons  and  140  adults),  the  average  work 
for  the  last  18  months  has  been  at  the  very  least  7  days,  5 
hours,  or  78i  hours  a  week.  For  the  six  weeks  ending  May 
2nd  this  year  (1862),  the  average  was  higher — 8  days  or  84 
hours  a  week."  Still  this  same  Mr.  Smith,  who  is  so  extremel}^ 
devoted  to  the  pluralis  majestatis,  adds  with  a  smile,  "  Machine 
work  is  not  great."     So  the  employers  in  the  block- printing 

1  This  is  not  to  be  taken  in  the  same  sense  as  our  surplus-labour  time.  These 
gentlemen  consider  10|  hours  of  labour  as  the  normal  working  day,  which  includes 
of  course  the  normal  surplus-labour.  After  this  begins  "  overtime  "  which  is  paid  a 
little  better.  It  will  be  seen  later  that  the  labour  expended  during  the  so-called 
normal  day  is  paid  below  its  value,  so  that  the  overtime  is  simply  a  capitalist  trick 
in  order  to  extort  more  surplus-labour,  which  it  would  still  be,  even  if  the  labour- 
power  expended  during  the  normal  working  day  were  properly  paid. 


232  Capitalist  Production, 

say  :  '  Hand  labour  is  more  healthy  than  machine- work."  On 
the  whole,  manufacturers  declare  with  indignation  against  the 
proposal  "  to  stop  the  machines  at  least  during  meal  times.' 
A  clause,  says  Mr.  Otley,  manager  of  a  wall-paper  factory  in 
the  Borough,  '*  which  allowed  work  between,  say  6  a.m.  and  9 
p.m.  .  .  .  would  suit  us  (!)  very  well,  but  the  factory  hours,  6 
a.m.  to  6  p.m.,  are  not  suitable.  Our  machine  i3  always 
stopped  for  dinner.  (What  generosity  1)  There  is  no  waste 
of  paper  and  colour  to  speak  of.  But,"  he  adds  sympatheti- 
cally, "  I  can  understand  the  loss  of  time  not  being  liked/ 
The  report  of  the  Commission  opines  with  naivete  that  the 
fear  of  some  "  leading  firms  "  of  losing  time,  i.e.,  the  time  for 
appropriating  the  labour  of  others,  and  thence  losing  profit 
is  not  a  sufiicient  reason  for  allowing  children  under  13,  and 
3'oung  persons  under  18,  working  12  to  16  hours  per  day,  to 
lose  their  dinner,  nor  for  giving  it  to  them  as  coal  and  water 
are  supplied  to  the  steam-engine,  soap  to  wool,  oil  to  the 
wheel — as  merely  auxiliary  material  to  the  instruments  of 
labour,  during  the  process  of  production  itself.^ 

No  branch  of  industry  in  England  (we  do  not  take  into 
account  the  making  of  bread  by  machinery  recently  intro- 
duced) has  preserved  up  to  the  present  day  a  method  of  pro- 
duction so  archaic,  so — as  we  see  from  the  poets  of  the  Roman 
Empire — pre-christian,  as  baking.  But  capital,  as  was  said 
earlier,  is  at  first  indifferent  as  to  the  technical  character  of  the 
labour-process  ;  it  begins  by  taking  it  just  as  it  finds  it. 

The  incredible  adulteration  of  bread,  especially  in  London, 
was  first  revealed  by  the  House  of  Commons  Committee  "  on 
the  adulteration  of  articles  of  food "  (1855-56),  and  Dr. 
Hassall's  work,  "  Adulterations  detected."  ^  The  consequence 
of  these  revelations  was  the  Act  of  August  6th,  1860,  "  for 
preventing  the  adulteration  of  articles  of  food  and  drink,"  an 
inoperative  law,  as  it  naturally  shows  the  tenderest  consider- 
ation for  every  free-trader  who  determines  by  the  buying  or 
selling  of  adulterated  commodities  "  to  turn  an  honest  penny." 

1 1.  c.     Evidence,  p.  123,  124,  125,  140,  and  54. 

2  Alum  finely  powdered,  or  mixed  with  salt,  is  a  normal  article  of  commerce  bear 
ing  the  significant  name  of  ' '  bakers'  stuff. " 

3  Soot  is  a  well-known  and  very  energetic  form  of  carbon,  and  forms  a  manure 


The  Working  Day,  233 

The  Committee  itself  formulated  more  or  less  naively  its  con- 
viction that  free-trade  meant  essentially  trade  with  adulter- 
ated, or  as  the  English  ingeniously  put  it,  "  sophisticated"  goods. 
In  fact  this  kind  of  sophistry  knows  better  than  Protagoras 
how  to  make  white  black,  and  black  white,  and  better  than 
the  Eleatics  how  to  demonstrate  ad  oculos  that  everything  is 
only  appearance.^ 

At  all  events  the  committee  had  directed  the  attention  of 
the  public  to  its  "  daily  bread,"  and  therefore  to  the  baking 
trade.  At  the  same  time  in  public  meetings  and  in  petitions 
to  Parliament  rose  the  cry  of  the  London  journeymen  bakers 
against  their  over-work,  &;c.  The  cry  was  so  urgent  that  Mr. 
H.  S.  Tremenheere,  also  a  member  of  the  Commission  of  1863 
several  times  mentioned,  was  appointed  Royal  Commissioner 
of  Inquiry.  His  report,^  together  with  the  evidence  given, 
roused  not  the  heart  of  the  public  but  its  stomach.  English- 
men, always  well  up  in  the  Bible,  knew  well  enough  that  man, 
unless  by  elective  grace  a  capitalist,  or  landlord,  or  sinecurist, 
is  commanded  to  eat  his  bread  in  the  sweat  of  his  brow,  but 
they  did  not  know  that  he  had  to  eat  daily  in  his  bread  a  certain 
quantity  of  human  perspiration  mixed  with  the  discharge  of 
abcesses,  cobwebs,  dead  black-beetles,  and  putrid  German  yeast, 
without  counting  alum,  sand,  and  other  agreeable  mineral  in- 
gredients. Without  any  regard  to  his  holiness,  Freetrade,  the 
free  baking-trade  was  therefore  placed  under  the  supervision 

that  capitalistic  chimney-sweeps  sell  to  English  farmers.  Now  in  1862  the  British 
juryman  had  in  a  law-suit  to  decide  whether  soot,  with  which,  unknown  to  the  buyer, 
90  %  of  dust  and  sand  are  mixed,  is  genuine  soot  in  the  commercial  sense  or  adulter- 
ated soot  in  the  legal  sense.  The  "  amis  du  commerce  "  decided  it  to  be  genuine 
commercial  soot,  and  non-suited  the  plaintiff  farmer,  who  had  in  addition  to  j)ay  the 
costs  of  the  suit. 

1  The  French  'chemist,  Chevallier,  in  his  treatise  on  the  "sophistications"  of 
commodities,  enumerates  for  many  of  the  600  or  more  articles  which  he  passes  in 
review,  10,  20,  30  different  methods  of  adulteration.  He  adds  that  he  does  not  know 
all  the  methods,  and  does  not  mention  all  that  he  knows.  He  gives  6  kinds  of 
adulteration  of  sugar,  9  of  olive  oil,  10  of  butter,  12  of  salt,  19  of  milk,  20  of  bread, 
23  of  brandy,  24  of  meal,  28  of  chocolate,  30  of  wine,  32  of  coffee,  etc.  Even  God 
Almighty  does  not  escape  this  fate.  See  Ronard  de  Card,  on  the  falsifications  of  the 
materials  of  the  Sacrament.  (De  la  falsification  des  substances  sacramentelles, 
Paris,  1856.) 

"  Report,  &c.,  relating  to  the  grievances  complained  of  by  the  journeymen  bakers, 
&c.,  London,  1862,^'  and  "  Second  Report,  &c.,  London,  1863." 


234  Capitalist  Production. 

of  the  State  inspectors  (Close  of  the  Parliamentary  session  of 
1863),  and  by  the  same  Act  of  Parliament,  work  from  9  in  the 
evening  to  5  in  the  morning  was  forbidden  for  journeymen 
bakers  nnder  18.  The  last  clause  speaks  volumes  as  to  the 
over- work  in  this  old-fashioned,  homely  line  of  business, 

"  The  work  of  a  London  journeyman  baker  begins,  as  a  rule, 
at  about  eleven  at  night.  At  that  hour  he  *  makes  the  dough,' 
— a  laborious  process,  which  lasts  from  half-an-hour  to  three 
quarters  of  an  hour,  according  to  the  size  of  the  batch  or  the 
labour  bestowed  upon  it.  He  then  lies  down  upon  the  knead- 
ing-board,  which  is  also  the  covering  of  the  trough  in  which 
the  dough  is  '  made  ; '  and  with  a  sack  under  him,  and  another 
rolled  up  as  a  pillow,  he  sleeps  for  about  a  couple  of  hours. 
He  is  then  engaged  in  a  rapid  and  continuous  labour  for  about 
five  hours — throwinor  out  the  dough,  '  scalino:  it  off,'  mouldinor 
it,  putting  it  into  the  oven,  preparing  and  baking  rolls  and 
fancy  bread,  taking  the  batch  bread  out  of  the  oven,  and  up 
into  the  shop,  fcc,  &c.  The  temperature  of  a  bakehouse  ranges 
from  about  75  to  upwards  of  90  degrees,  and  in  the  smaller 
bakehouses  approximates  usually  to  the  higher  rather  than  to 
the  lower  degree  of  heat.  When  the  business  of  making  the 
bread,  rolls,  fee,  is  over,  that  of  its  distribution  begins,  and  a 
considerable  proportion  of  the  journeymen  in  the  trade,  after 
working  hard  in  the  manner  described  during  the  night,  are 
upon  their  legs  for  many  hours  during  the  day,  carrying  baskets, 
or  wheeling  hand-carts,  and  sometimes  again  in  the  bakehouse, 
leaving  off  work  at  various  hours  between  1  and  6  p.m. 
according  to  the  season  of  the  year,  or  the  amount  and  nature 
of  their  master's  business ;  while  others  are  again  engaged  in 
the  bakehouse  in  '  bringing  out '  more  batches  until  late  in  the 
afternoon.^ .  .  .  During  what  is  called  '  the  London  season,'  the 
operatives  belonging  to  the  '  full-priced  '  bakers  at  the  West 
End  of  the  town,  generally  begin  work  at  11  p.m.,  and  are  en- 
gaged in  making  the  bread,  with  one  or  two  short  (sometimes 
very  short)  intervals  of  rest,  up  to  8  o'clock  the  next  morning. 
They  are  then  engaged  all  day  long,  up  to  4,  5,  6,  and  as  late 
as  7  o'clock  in  the  evening  carrying  out  bread,  or  sometimes  in 

1.  c.  First  Report,  &c.,  p.  vi. 


The  Working  Day.  235 

the  afternoon  in  the  bakehouse  again,  assisting  in  the  biscuit- 
baking.  They  may  have,  after  they  have  done  their  work, 
sometimes  five  or  six,  sometimes  only  four  or  five  hours'  sleep 
before  they  begin  again.  On  Fridays  they  always  begin 
sooner,  some  about  ten  o'clock,  and  continue  in  some  cases,  at 
work,  either  in  making  or  delivering  the  bread  up  to  8  p.m.  on 
Saturday  night,  but  more  generally  up  to  4  or  5  o'clock, 
Sunday  morning.  On  Sundays  the  men  must  attend  twice  or 
three  times  during  the  day  for  an  hour  or  two  to  make  pre- 
parations for  the  next  day's  bread The  men  employed 

by  the  underselling  masters  (who  sell  their  bread  under  the 
'  full  price,'  and  who,  as  already  pointed  out,  comprise  three- 
fourths  of  the  London  bakers)  have  not  only  to  work  on  the 
average  longer  hours,  but  their  work  is  almost  entirely  confined 
to  the  bakehouse.  The  underselling  masters  generally  sell  their 
bread.  ...  in  the  shop.  If  they  send  it  out,  which  is  not  common, 
except  as  supplying  chandlers'  shops,  they  usually  employ  other 
hands  for  that  purpose.     It  is  not  their  practice  to  deliver 

bread  from  house  to  house.    Towards  the  end  of  the  week 

the  men  begin  on  Thursday  night  at  10  o'clock,  and  continue  on 
with  only  slight  intermission  until  late  on  Saturday  evening."^ 
Even  the  bourgeois  intellect  understands  the  position  of  the 
"  underselling  "  masters.  "  The  unpaid  labour  of  the  men  was 
made  the  source  whereby  the  competition  was  carried  on."^ 
And  the  "  full-priced  "  baker  denounces  his  underselling  com- 
petitors to  the  Commission  of  Inquiry  as  thieves  of  foreign 
labour  and  adulterators.  "They  only  exist  now  by  first  de- 
frauding the  public,  and  next  getting  18  hours'  work  out  of 
their  men  for  12  hours'  wages."  ^ 

The  adulteration  of  bread  and  the  formation  o£  a  class  of 
bakers  that  sells  the  bread  below  the  full  price,  date  from  the 
beginning  of  the  18th  century,  from  the  time  when  the 
corporate  character  of  the  trade  was  lost,  and  the  capitalist  in 
the  form  of  the  miller  or  flour-factor,  rises  behind  the  nominal 
master  baker.^     Thus  was  laid  the  foundation  of  capitalistic 

1 1.  c.  p.  Ixxi.  2  George  Read,  The  History  of  Baking,  London,  1848,  p.  16. 

3  Report  (First)  &c.     Evidence  of  the  "full-priced  "  baker  Cheeseman,  p.  108. 

4  George  Read,  1.  c.     At  the  end  of  the  17th  and  the  beginning  of  the  18th  centuries 
the  factors  (agents)  that  crowded  into  every  possible  trade  were  still  denounced  as 


236  Capitalist  Production. 

production  in  this  trade,  of  the  unlimited  extension  of  the 
working  day  and  of  night  labour,  although  the  latter  only 
since  1824  gained  a  serious  footing,  even  in  London.^ 

After  what  has  just  been  said,  it  will  be  understood  that  the 
Report  of  the  Commission  classes  journeymen  bakers  among 
the  short-lived  labourers,  who,  having  by  good  luck  escaped  the 
normal  decimation  of  the  children  of  the  working-class,  rarely 
reach  the  age  of  42.  Nevertheless,  the  baking  trade  is  always 
overwhelmed  with  applicants.  The  sources  of  the  supply  of 
these  labour-powers  to  London  are  Scotland,  the  western  agri- 
cultural districts  of  England,  and  Germany. 

In  the  years  1858-60,  the  journeymen  bakers  in  Ireland 
organised  at  their  own  expense  great  meetings  to  agitate 
against  night  and  Sunday  work.  The  public — e.g.,  at  the 
Dublin  meeting  in  May,  18(j0 — took  their  part  with  Irish 
warmth.  As  result  of  this  movement,  day  labour  alone  was 
successfully  established  in  Wexford,  Kilkenny,  Clonmel,  Water- 
ford,  &;c.  "  In  Limerick,  where  the  grievances  of  the  journey- 
men are  demonstrated  to  be  excessive,  the  movement  has  been 
defeated  by  the  opposition  of  the  master  bakers,  the  miller 
bakers  being  the  greatest  opponents.  'J'he  example  of  Limerick 
led  to  a  retrogression  in  Ennis  and  Tipperary.  In  Cork,  where 
the  strongest  possible  demonstration  of  feeling  took  place,  the 
masters,  by  exercising  their  power  of  turning  the  men  out  of 
employment,  have  defeated  the  movement.  In  Dublin,  the 
master  bakers  have  offered  the  most  determined  opposition  to 
the  movement,  and  by  discountenancing  as  much  as  possible 
the  journeymen  promoting  it,  have  succeeded  in  leading  the 
men  into  acquiescence  in  Sunday  work  and  night  work,  con- 
trary to  the  convictions  of  the  men."^ 

The  Committee  of  the  English  Government,  which  Govern- 
ment, in  Ireland,  is  armed  to  the  te'eth,  and  general^  knows 
how  to  show  it,  remonstrates  in  mild,  though  funereal,  tones 

"  public  nuisances."  Thus  the  Grand  Jury  at  the  quarter  session  of  the  Justices  of 
the  Peace  for  the  County  of  Somerset,  addressed  a  presentment  to  the  Lower  House 
which,  among  other  things,  states,  "  that  these  factors  of  Black  well  Hall  are  a  Public 
Nuisance  and  Prejudice  to  the  Clothing  Trade,  and  ought  to  be  put  down  as  a 
Nuisance."    The  case  of  our  English  Wool,  &c.,  London,  1685,  p.  6,  7. 

1  First  Eeport,  &c. 

2  Report  of  Committee  on  the  Baking  Trade  in  Ireland  for  1861. 


The  Working  Day,  237 

with  the  implacable  master  bakers  of  Dublin,  Limerick,  Cork, 
&;c. :  "  The  Committee  believe  that  the  hours  of  labour  are 
limited  by  natural  laws,  which  cannot  be  violated  with  im- 
punity. That  for  master  bakers  to  induce  their  workmen,  by 
the  fear  of  losing  employment,  to  violate  their  religious  con- 
victions and  their  better  feelings,  to  disobey  the  laws  of  the 
land,  and  to  disregard  public  opinion  (this  all  refers  to  Sunday 
labour),  is  calculated  to  provoke  ill-feeling  between  workmen 
and  masters,  .  .  .  and  affords  an  example  dangerous  to  religion, 
morality,  and  social  order.  .  .  .  The  Committee  believe  that 
any  constant  work  beyond  12  hours  a-day  encroaches  on  the 
domestic  and  private  life  of  the  working  man,  and  so  leads  to 
disastrous  moral  results,  interfering  with  each  man's  home,  and 
the  discharge  of  his  family  duties  as  a  son,  a  brother,  a  husband, 
a  father.  That  work  beyond  12  hours  has  a  tendency  to 
undermine  the  health  of  the  working  man,  and  so  leads  to 
premature  old  age  and  death,  to  the  great  injury  of  families  of 
working  men,  thus  deprived  of  the  care  and  support  of  the 
head  of  the  family  when  most  required."^ 

So  far,  we  have  dealt  with  Ireland.  On  the  other  side  of 
the  channel,  in  Scotland,  the  agricultural  labourer,  the  plough- 
man, protests  against  his  13-14  hours'  work  in  the  most  in- 
clement climate,  with  4  hours'  additional  work  on  Sunday  (in 
this  land  of  Sabbatarians  l),^  whilst,  at  the  same  time,  three 
railway  men  are  standing  before  a  London  coroner's  jury — a 
guard,  an  engine-driver,  a  signalman.  A  tremendous  railway 
accident  has  hurried  hundreds  of  passengers  into  another 
world.     The  negligence  of  the  employes  is  the  cause  of  the 

u.  c. 

2  Public  meeting  of  agricultural  labourers  at  Lasswade,  near  Edinburgh,  January 
5tli,  1866.  (See  "Workman's  Advocate,"  January  13th,  1866.)  The  formation 
since  the  close  of  1865  of  a  Trades'  Union  among  the  agricultural  labourers  at  first  in 
Scotland  is  a  historic  event.  In  one  of  the  most  oppressed  agricultural  districts  of 
England,  Buckinghamshire,  the  labourers,  in  March,  1867,  made  a  great  strike  for 
the  raising  of  their  weekly  wage  from  9-10  shillings  to  12  shillings.  (It  will  be  seen 
from  the  preceding  passage  that  the  movement  of  the  English  agricultural  proletariat, 
entirely  crushed  since  the  suppression  of  its  violent  manifestations  after  1830,  and 
especially  since  the  introduction  of  the  new  Poor  Laws,  begins  again  in  the  sixties, 
until  it  becomes  finally  epoch-making  in  1872.  I  return  to  this  in  the  2nd  volume, 
as  well  as  to  the  blue  books  that  have  appeared  since  1867  on  the  positipn  of  the  Eng- 
lish land  labourers.     Addendum  to  the  3rd  ed.) 


238  Capitalist  Production. 

misfortune.  They  declare  with  one  voice  before  the  jury  that 
ten  or  twelve  years  before,  their  labour  only  lasted  eight  hours 
a-day.  During  the  last  five  or  six  years  it  had  been  screwed 
up  to  14,  18,  and  20  hours,  and  under  a  specially  severe  pres- 
sure of  holiday-makers,  at  times  of  excursion  trains,  it  often 
lasted  for  40  or  50  hours  without  a  break.  They  were  ordinary 
men,  not  Cyclops.  At  a  certain  point  their  labour-power  failed. 
Torpor  seized  them.  Their  brain  ceased  to  think,  their  ej^es  to 
see.  The  thoroughly  "  respectable  "  British  jurymen  answered 
by  a  verdict  that  sent  them  to  the  next  assizes  on  a  charge  of 
manslaughter,  and,  in  a  gentle  "rider"  to  their  verdict,  ex- 
pressed the  pious  hope  that  the  capitalistic  magnates  of  the  rail- 
ways would,  in  future,  be  more-  extravagant  in  the  purchase  of  a 
sufficient  quantity  of  labour-power,  and  more  "  abstemious," 
more  "  self-denying,"  more  "  thrifty,"  in  the  draining  of  paid 
labour-power. 

From  the  motley  crowd  of  labourers  of  all  callings,  ages, 
sexes,  that  press  on  us  more  busily  than  the  souls  of  the  slain 
on  Ulysses,  on  whom — without  referring  to  the  blue  books 
under  their  arms — we  see  at  a  glance  the  mark  of  over- work, 
let  us  take  two  more  figures  whose  striking  contrast  proves 
that  before  capital  all  men  are  alike — a  milliner  and  a  black- 
smith. 

^  *'  Reynolds'  Newspaper,"  January,  1866. — Every  week  this  same  paper  has, 
under  the  sensational  headings,  "  Fearful  and  fatal  accidents,"  "  Appalling  tragedies," 
&c.,  a  whole  list  of  fresh  railway  catastrophes.  On  these  an  employe  on  the  North 
Staffordshire  line  comments  :  "  Everyone  knows  the  consequences  that  may  occur  if 
the  driver  and  fireman  of  a  locomotive  engine  are  not  continually  on  the  look-out. 
How  can  that  be  expected  from  a  man  who  has  been  at  such  work  for  29  or  30  hours, 
exj)osed  to  the  weather,  and  without  rest.  The  following  is  an  example  which  is  of 
very  frequent  occurrence  : — One  fireman  commenced  work  on  the  Monday  morning 
at  a  very  early  hour.  When  he  had  finished  what  is  called  a  day's  work,  he  had 
been  on  duty  14  hours  50  minutes.  Before  he  had  time  to  get  his  tea,  he  was  again 
called  on  for  duty.  .  .  .  The  next  time  he  finished  he  had  been  on  duty  14  hours 
25  minutes,  making  a  total  of  29  hours  15  minutes  without  intermission.  The  rest 
of  the  week's  work  was  made  up  as  follows : — Wednesday,  15  hours  ;  Thursday,  15 
hours  35  minutes ;  Friday,  14^  hours  ;  Saturday,  14  hours  10  minutes,  making  a 
total  for  the  week  of  88  hours  40  minutes.  Now,  sir,  fancy  his  astonishment  on 
being  paid  6|  days  for  the  whole.  Thinking  it  was  a  mistake,  he  ai:)plied  to  the  time- 
keeper, .  .  .  and  inquh-ed  what  they  considered  a  day's  work,  and  was  told  13  hours 
for  a  goods  man  (i.e.,  78  hours).  .  .  .  He  then  asked  for  what  he  had  made  over 
and  above  the  78  hours  per  week,  but  was  refused.  However,  he  was  at  last  told 
they  would  give  him  another  quarter,  t.e.,  lOd."    1.  c,  4th  February,  1866. 


The  Working  Day,  239 

In  the  last  week  of  June,  1863,  all  the  London  daily  papers 
published  a  paragraph  with  the  "  sensational "  heading,  "  Death 
from  simple  over-work."  It  dealt  with  the  death  of  the 
milliner,  Mary  Anne  Walkley,  20  years  of  age,  emploj'-ed  in  a 
highly-respectable  dressmaking  establishment,  exploited  by  a 
lady  with  the  pleasant  name  of  Elise.  The  old,  often-told 
story,-  was  once  more  recounted.  This  girl  worked,  on  an 
average,  16  J  hours,  during  the  season  often  30  hours,  without  a 
break,  whilst  her  failing  labour-power  was  revived  by  occasional 
supplies  of  sherry,  port,  or  coffee.  It  was  just  now  the  height 
of  the  season.  It  was  necessary  to  conjure  up  in  the  twinkling 
of  an  eye  the  gorgeous  dresses  for  the  noble  ladies  bidden  to 
the  ball  in  honour  of  the  newly-imported  Princess  of  Wales. 
Mary  Anne  Walkley  had  worked  without  intermission  for  26^ 
hours,  with  60  other  girls,  30  in  one  room,  that  only  afforded  J 
of  the  cubic  feet  of  air  required  for  them.  At  night,  they  slept 
in  pairs  in  one  of  the  stifling  holes  into  which  the  bedroom  was 
divided  by  partitions  of  board.^  And  this  was  one  of  the  best 
millinery  establishments  in  London.  Mary  Anne  Walkley  fell 
ill  on  the  Friday,  died  on  Sunday,  without,  to  the  astonish- 
ment of  Madame  Elise,  having  previously  completed  the  work 
in  hand.     The  doctor,  Mr.  Keys,  called  too  late  to  the  death- 

1  Cf.     F.  Engels.     1.  c,  pp.  253,  254. 

2  Dr.  Letheby,  Consulting  Physician  of  the  Board  of  Health,  declared  :  "  The  mini- 
mum of  air  for  each  adult  ought  to  be  in  a  sleeping  room  300,  and  in  a  dwelling  room 
500  cubic  feet."  Dr.  Richardson,  Senior  Physician  to  one  of  the  London  Hospitals  : 
"  With  needlewomen  of  all  kinds,  including  milliners,  dressmakers,  and  ordinary 
sempstresses,  there  are  three  miseries — over-work,  deficient  air,  and  either  deficient 
food  or  deficient  digestion.  .  .  .  Needlework,  in  the  main,  ...  is  infinitely 
better  adapted  to  women  than  to  men.  But  the  mischiefs  of  the  trade,  in  the 
metropolis  especially,  are  that  it  is  monopolised  by  some  twenty-six  capitalists,  who, 
under  the  advantages  that  spring  from  capital,  can  bring  in  capital  to  force  economy 
out  of  labour.  This  power  tells  throughout  the  whole  class.  If  a  dressmaker  can 
get  a  little  circle  of  customers,  such  is  the  competition  that,  in  her  home,  she  must 
work  to  the  death  to  hold  together,  and  this  same  over- work  she  mast  of  necessity 
inflict  on  any  who  may  assist  her.  If  she  fail,  or  do  not  try  independently,  she  must 
join  an  establishment,  where  her  labour  is  not  less,  but  where  her  money  is  safe. 
Placed  thus,  she  becomes  a  mere  slave,  tossed  about  with  the  variations  of  society. 
Now  at  home,  in  one  room,  starving,  or  near  to  it,  then  engaged  15,  16,  aye,  even  18 
hours  out  of  the  24,  in  an  air  that  is  scarcely  tolerable,  and  on  food  which,  even  if  it 
be  good,  cannot  be  digested  in  the  absence  of  pure  air.  On  these  victims,  consump- 
tion, which  is  purely  a  disease  of  bad  air,  feeds."  Dr.  Richardson:  "Work  and 
Overwork,"  in  "  Social  Science  Review,"  18th  July,  1863. 


240  Capitalist  Production, 

bed,  duly  bore  witness  before  the  coroner's  jury  that  "  Mar} 
Anne  Walkley  had  died  from  long  hours  of  work  in  an  over- 
crowded workroom,  and  a  too  small  and  badly- ventilated  bed- 
room." In  order  to  give  the  doctor  a  lesson  in  good  manners, 
the  coroner's  jury  thereupon  brought  in  a  verdict  that  "  the 
deceased  had  died  of  apoplexy,  but  there  was  reason  to  fear 
that  her  death  had  been  accelerated  b}''  over- work  in  an  over- 
crowded workroom,  &c."  "  Our  white  slaves,"  cried  the 
"Morning  Star,"  the  organ  of  the  free-traders,  Cobden  and 
Bright,  "  our  white  slaves,  who  are  toiled  into  the  grave,  for 
the  most  part  silently  pine  and  die." 

"It  is  not  in  dressmakers'  rooms  that  working  to  death  is 
the  order  of  the  day,  but  in  a  thousand  other  places  ;  in  every 
place  I  had  almost  said,  where  *  a  thriving  business  '  has  to  be 
done.  .  .  .  We  will  take  the  blacksmith  as  a  type.  If 
the  poets  were  true,  there  is  no  man  so  hearty,  so  merr}^,  as 
the  blacksmith ;  he  rises  early  and  strikes  his  sparks  before 
the  sun  ;  he  eats  and  drinks  and  sleeps  as  no  other  man. 
Working  in  moderation,  he  is,  in  fact,  in  one  of  the  best  of 
human  positions,  physically  speaking.  But  we  follow  him  into 
the  city  or  town,  and  we  see  the  stress  of  work  on  that  strong 
man,  and  what  then  is  his  j)osition  in  the  death-rate  of  his 
country.  In  Marylebone,  blacksmiths  die  at  the  rate  of  31  per 
thousand  per  annum,  or  11  above  the  mean  of  the  male  adults 
of  the  country  in  its  entirety.      The  occupation,  instinctive 

1  "  Morning  Star,"  23rd  June,  1863.— The  "Times  "  made  use  of  the  circumstance 
to  defend  the  American  slave  owners  against  Bright,  &c.  "  Very  many  of  us  think," 
says  a  leader  of  July  2nd,  18G3,  ' '  that,  while  we  work  our  own  young  women  to 
death,  using  the  scourge  of  starvation,  instead  of  the  crack  of  the  whip,  as  the  instru- 
ment of  compulsion,  we  have  scarcely  a  right  to  hound  on  fire  and  slaughter  against 
families  who  were  born  slave  owners,  and  who,  at  least,  feed  their  slaves  well,  and 
work  them  lightly. "  In  the  same  manner,  the  ' '  Standard, "  a  Tory  organ,  fell  foul 
of  the  Rev.  Newman  Hall :  "  He  excommunicated  the  slave  owners,  but  prays  with 
the  fine  folk  who,  without  remorse,  make  the  omnibus  drivers  and  conductors  of 
London,  &c.,  work  16  hours  a-day  for  the  wages  of  a  dog."  Finally,  spake  the  oracle, 
Thomas  Carlyle,  of  whom  I  wrote,  in  1850,  "Zum  Teufel  ist  der  Genius,  der  Kultus 
ist  geblieben."  In  a  short  parable,  he  reduces  the  one  great  event  of  contemporary 
histox-y,  the  American  civil  war,  to  this  level,  that  the  Peter  of  the  North  wants  to 
break  the  head  of  the  Paul  of  the  South  with  all  his  might,  because  the  Peter  of  the 
North  hires  his  labour  by  the  day,  and  the  Paul  of  the  South  hires  his  by  the  life. 
("  Macmillan's  Magazine."  Ilias  Americana  in  nuce.  August,  1863.)  Thus,  the 
bubble  of  Tory  sympathy  for  the  urban  workers — by  no  means  for  the  rural — has 
burst  at  last.     The  sum  of  all  is — slavery  ! 


The  Working  Day,  241 

almost  as  a  portion  of  human  art,  unobjectionable  as  a  branch 
of  human  industry,  is  made  by  mere  excess  of  work,  the  de- 
stroyer of  the  man.  He  can  strike  so  many  blows  per  day,  walk 
so  many  steps,  breathe  so  many  breaths,  produce  so  much 
work,  and  live  an  average,  say  of  fifty  years ;  he  is  made  to 
strike  so  many  more  blows,  to  walk  so  many  more  steps,  to 
breathe  so  many  more  breaths  per  day,  and  to  increase  alto- 
gether a  fourth  of  his  life.  He  meets  the  effort ;  the  result  is, 
that  producing  for  a  limited  time  a  fourth  more  work,  he  dies 
at  37  for  50."'^ 


SECTION   4. — DAY   AND   NIGHT   WORK.       THE   RELAY   SYSTEM. 

Constant  capital,  the  means  of  production,  considered  from 
the  standpoint  of  the  creation  of  surplus-value,  only  exist  to 
absorb  labour,  and  with  every  drop  of  labour  a  proportional 
quantity  of  surplus-labour.  While  they  fail  to  do  this,  their 
mere  existence  causes  a  relative  loss  to  the  capitalist,  for  they 
represent  during  the  time  they  lie  fallow,  a  useless  advance  of 
capital.  And  this  loss  becomes  positive  and  absolute  as  soon 
as  the  intermission  of  their  employment  necessitates  additional 
outlay  at  the  recommencement  of  work.  The  prolongation  of 
the  working  day  beyond  the  limits  of  the  natural  day,  into 
the  night,  only  acts  as  a  palliative.  It  quenches  only  in  a  slight 
degree  the  vampire  thirst  for  the  living  blood  of  labour.  To 
appropriate  labour  during  all  the  24  hours  of  the  day  is,  therefore, 
the  inherent  tendency  of  capitalist  production.  But  as  it  is 
physically  impossible  to  exploit  the  same  individual  labour- 
power  constantly  during  the  night  as  well  as  the  day,  to  over- 
come this  physical  hindrance,  an  alternation  becomes  necessary/ 
between  the  workpeople  whose  powers  are  exhausted  by  day, 
and  those  who  are  used  up  by  night.  This  alternation  may  be 
effected  In  various  ways ;  e.g.,  it  may  be  so  arranged  that  part 
of  the  workers  are  one  week  employed  on  day  work,  the  next 
week  on  night  work.  It  is  well-known  that  this  relay  system, 
this  alternation  of  two  sets  of  workers,  held  full  sway  in  the 
full-blooded  youth-time  of  the  English  cotton  manufacture,  and 

1  Dr  Richardson,  1.  c 
Q 


242  Capitalist  Production, 

that  at  the  present  time  it  still  flourishes,  among  others,  in  the 
cotton  spinning  of  the  Moscow  district.  This  24  hours'  process 
of  production  exists  to-day  as  a  system  in  many  of  the 
branches  of  industry  of  Great  Britain  that  are  still  "  free,"  in 
the  blast-furnaces,  forges,  plate-rolling  mills,  and  other  metal- 
lurgical establishments  in  England,  Wales,  and  Scotland.  The 
working  time  here  includes,  besides  the  24  hours  of  the  6 
working  days,  a  great  part  also  of  the  24  hours  of  Sunday. 
The  workers  consist  of  men  and  women,  adults  and  children 
of  both  sexes.  The  agesof  the  children  and  young  persons  run 
through  all  intermediate  grades,  from  8  (in  some  cases  from  6) 
to  18.^ 

In  some  branches  of  industry,  the  girls  and  women  work 
through  the  night  together  with  the  males.- 

Placing  on  one  side  the  generally  injurious  influence  of  night- 
labour,''  the  duration  of  the  process  of  production,  unbroken  dur- 

1  Children's  Employment  Commission.   Third  Report.   London,  1864,  p.  iv.,  v.,  vi. 

2  "Both  in  Staffordshire  and  in  South  Wales  young  girls  and  women  are  employed 
on  the  pit  banks  and  on  the  coke  heaps,  not  only  by  day  but  also  by  night.  This 
practice  has  been  often  noticed  in  Reports  presented  to  Parliament,  as  being  attended 
with  great  and  notorious  evils.  These  females  employed  with  the  men,  hardly  dis- 
tinguished from  them  in  their  dress,  and  begrimed  with  dirt  and  smoke,  are  exposed 
to  the  deterioration  of  character,  arising  from  the  loss  of  self-respect,  which  can 
hardly  fail  to  follow  from  their  unfeminine  occupation."  (1.  c.  194.,  p.  xxvi.  Cf. 
Fourth  Report  (1865),  61,  p.  xiii.)    It  is  the  same  in  glass-works. 

3  A  steel  manufacturer  who  employs  children  in  night-labour  remarked  :  "  It 
seems  but  natural  that  boys  who  work  at  night  cannot  sleep  and  get  proper  rest  by 
day,  but  will  be  running  about."  (1.  c.  Fourth  Report,  63,  p.  xiii.)  On  the  import- 
ance of  sunlight  for  the  maintenance  and  growth  of  the  body,  a  physician  writes  : 
' '  Light  also  acts  upon  the  tissues  of  the  body  directly  in  hardening  them  and  supporting 
their  elasticity.  The  muscles  of  animals,  when  they  are  deprived  of  a  proper  amount 
of  light,  become  soft  and  inelastic,  the  nervous  power  loses  its  tone  from  defective 

stimulation,  and  the  elaboration  of  all  growth  seems  to  be  perverted In 

the  case  of  children,  constant  access  to  plenty  of  light  during  the  day,  and  to  the 
direct  rays  of  the  sun  for  a  part  of  it,  is  most  essential  to  health.  Light  assists  in  the 
elaboration  of  good  plastic  blood,  and  hardens  the  fibre  after  it  has  been  laid  down. 
It  also  acts  as  a  stimulus  upon  the  organs  of  sight,  and  by  this  means  brings  about 
more  activity  in  the  various  cerebral  functions."  Dr.  W.  Strange,  Senior  Physician 
of  the  Worcester  General  Hospital,  from  whose  work  on  "Health"  (1864)  this 
passage  is  taken,  writes  in  a  letter  to  Mr.  White,  one  of  the  commissioners  :  "  I  have 
had  opportunities  formerly,  when  in  Lancashire,  of  observing  the  effects  of  night- work 
upon  children,  and  I  have  no  hesitation  in  saying,  contrary  to  what  some  employers 
were  fond  of  asserting,  those  children  who  were  subjected  to  it  soon  suffered  in  their 
wealth."  (1.  c.  284.,  p.  55.)  That  such  a  question  should  furnish  the  material  of 
f.erious  controversy,  shows  plainly  how  capitalist  production  acts  on  the  brain- 
f  unctions  of  capitalists  and  their  retainers. 


The   Working  Day.  243 

ing  the  24  hours,  offers  very  welcome  opportunities  of  exceeding 
the  limits  of  the  normal  working  day,  e.g.,  in  the  branches  of 
industry  already  mentioned,  which  are  of  an  exceedingly 
fatiguing  nature  ;  the  official  working  day  means  for  each 
worker  usually  12  hours  by  night  or  day.  But  the  over- work 
beyond  this  amount  is  in  many  cases,  to  use  the  words  of  the 
English  official  report,  "  tiuly  fearful."^ 

''  It  is  impossible,"  the  report  continues,  "  for  any  mind  to 
realise  the  amount  of  work  described  in  the  following  passages 
as  being  performed  by  boys  of  from  9  to  12  years  of  age  .... 
without  coming  irresistibly  to  the  conclusion  that  such  abuses 
of  the  power  of  parents  and  of  employers  can  no  longer  be 
allowed  to  exist."^ 

"The  practice  of  boys  working  at  all  by  day  and  night 
turns  either  in  the  usual  course  of  things,  or  at  pressing  times, 
seems  inevitably  to  open  the  door  to  their  not  unfrequently 
working  unduly  long  hours.  These  hours  are,  indeed,  in  some 
cases,  not  only  cruelly  but  even  incredibly  long  for  children. 
Amongst  a  number  of  boys  it  will,  of  course,  not  unfrequently 
happen  that  one  or  moi-e  are  from  some  cause  absent.  When 
this  happens,  their  place  is  made  up  by  one  or  more  boys, 
who  work  in  the  other  turn.  That  this  is  a  well  understood 
system  is  plain  .  .  .  from  the  answer  of  the  manager  of 
some  large  rolling-mills,  who,  when  I  asked  him  how  the 
place  of  the  boys  absent  from  their  turn  was  made  up,  'I 
daresay,  sir,  you  know  that  as  well  as  I  do,'  and  admitted  the 
fact."^ 

"At  a  rolling-mill  where  the  proper  hours  were  from  6  a.m. 
to  h\  p.m.,  a  boy  worked  about  four  nights  every  week  till 
8|  p.m.  at  least  .  .  .  and  this  for  six  months.  Another,  at  9 
years  old,  sometimes  made  three  12-hour  shifts  running,  and, 
when  10,  has  made  two  days  and  two  nights  running."  A 
third,  "now  10  .  .  .  worked  from  6  a.m.  till  12  p.m.  three 
nights,  and  till  9  p.m.  the  other  nights."  "Another,  now  13, 
.  .  .  worked  from  6  p.m.  till  12  noon  next  day,  for  a  week 
together,  and  sometimes  for  three  shifts  together,  e.g.,  from 
Monday  morning  till  Tuesday  night."     "  Another,  now  12,  has 

J 1.  c.  57,  p.  xii.  2  1.  c.    Fourth  Report  (18G5),  58,  p.  xii.  »  1.  c. 


244  Capitalist  Prodztction. 

worked  in  an  iron  foundry  at  Stavely  from  6  a.m.  till  12  p.m. 
for  a  fortnight  on  end  ;  could  not  do  it  any  more."  "  George 
Allinsworth,  age  9,  came  here  as  cellar-boy  last  Friday ;  next 
morning  we  had  to  begin  at  3,  so  I  stopped  here  all  night. 
Live  five  miles  off.  Slept  on  the  floor  of  the  furnace,  over 
head,  with  an  apron  under  me,  and  a  bit  of  a  jacket  over  me. 
The  two  other  days  I  have  been  here  at  6  a.m.  Aye  !  it  is  hot 
in  here.  Before  I  came  here  I  was  nearly  a  year  at  the  same 
work  at  some  works  in  the  country.  Began  there,  too,  at  3  on 
Saturday  morning — always  did,  but  was  very  gain  [near]  home, 
and  could  sleep  at  home.  Other  days  I  began  at  6  in  the  morn- 
ing, and  gi'en  over  at  6  or  7  in  the  evening,"  &;c.^ 

1  1.  c,  p.  xiii.  The  degree  of  culture  of  these  "  labour-powers  "  must  naturally  be 
such  as  appears  in  the  following  dialogues  with  one  of  the  commissioners  :  Jeremiah 
Haynes,  age  12 — "Four  times  four  is  8  ;  4 fours  are  16,  A  king  is  him  that  has  all  the 
money  and  gold.  We  have  a  King  (told  it  is  a  Queen),  they  call  her  the  Princess 
A.lexandra.  Told  that  she  married  the  Queen's  son.  The  Queen's  son  is  the  Princess 
Alexandra.  A  Princess  is  a  man."  William  Turner,  age  12 — "Don't  live  in  Eng- 
land. Think  it  is  a  country,  but  didn't  know  before."  John  Morris,  age  14  — 
"Have  heard  say  that  God  made  the  world,  and  that  all  the  people  was  drownded 
but  one  ;  heard  say  that  one  was  a  little  bird."  William  Smith,  age  15—"  God 
made  man,  man  made  woman."  Edward  Taylor,  age  15 — "Do  not  know  of  Lon- 
don." Henry  Matthewman,  age  17 — "Had  been  to  chapel,  but  missed  a  good  many 
times  lately.  One  name  that  they  preached  about  was  Jesus  Christ,  but  I  cannot 
say  any  others,  and  I  cannot  tell  anything  about  him.  He  was  not  killed,  but  died 
like  other  people.  He  was  not  the  same  as  other  people  in  some  ways,  because  he 
was  religious  in  some  ways,  and  others  isn't."  (1.  c.  p.  xv.)  "  The  devil  is  a  good 
person.  I  don't  know  where  he  lives."  "  Christ  was  a  wicked  man."  "  This  girl  spelt 
God  as  dog,  and  did  not  know  the  name  of  the  queen."  ("  Ch.  Employment  Comm. 
V.  Report,  18G3,"  p.  55,  n.  278.)  The  same  system  obtains  in  the  glass  and  paper 
works  as  in  the  metallurgical,  already  cited.  In  the  paper  factories,  where  the  paper 
is  made  by  machinery,  night- work  is  the  rule  for  all  processes,  except  rag-sorting. 
In  some  cases  night- work,  by  relays,  is  carried  on  incessantly  through  the  whole  week, 
usually  from  Sunday  night  until  midnight  of  the  following  Saturday.  Those  who  are 
on  day-work  work  5  days  of  12,  and  1  day  of  18  hours ;  those  on  night-work  5  nights  of 
12,  and  1  of  6  hours  in  each  week.  In  other  cases  each  set  works  24  hours  consecu- 
tively on  alternate  days,  one  set  working  6  hours  on  Monday,  and  18  on  Saturday 
to  make  up  the  24  hours.  In  other  cases  an  intermediate  system  prevails,  by  which 
all  employed  on  the  paper-making  machinery  work  15  or  16  hours  every  day  in  the 
week.  This  system,  says  Commissioner  Lord,  *' seems  to  combine  all  the  evils  of 
both  the  12  hours'  and  the  24  hours'  relays."  Children  under  13,  young  persons  under 
18,  and  women,  work  under  this  night  system.  Sometimes  under  the  12  hours' 
system  they  are  obliged,  on  account  of  the  non-appearance  of  those  that  oiight  to 
relieve  them,  to  work  a  doiable  turn  of  24  hours.  The  evidence  proves  that  boys 
and  girls  very  often  work  over-time,  which,  not  unfrequently,  extends  to  24  or  even  3G 
hours  of  uninterrupted  toil.  In  the  continuous  and  unvarying  process  of  glazing  are 
found  girls  of  12  who  work  the  whole  month  14  hours  a  day,  "  without  any  regular 


The   Working  Day,  245 

Let  us  now  hear  how  capital  itself  regards  this  24  hours* 
system.  The  extreme  forms  of  the  system,  its  abuse  in  the 
"  cruel  and  incredible  "  extension  of  the  working  day  are  natur- 
ally passed  over  in  silence.  Capital  only  speaks  of  the  system 
in  its  "  normal "  form, 

Messrs.  Naylor  &  Vickers,  steel  manufacturers,  who  employ 
between  600  and  700  persons,  among  whom  only  10  per  cent, 
are  under  18,  and  of  those,  only  20  boys  under  18  work  in 
night  sets,  thus  express  themselves  :  *'The  boys  do  not  suffer 
from  the  heat.  The  temperature  is  probably  from  86°  to  90"*. 
.  .  .  .  At  the  forges  and  in  the  rolling-mills  the  hands 
work  night  and  day,  in  relays,  but  all  the  other  parts  of  the 
work  are  day  work,  i.^.,  from  6  a.m.  to  6  p.m.  In  the  forge  tlie 
hours  are  from  12  to  12.  Some  of  the  hands  always  work  in 
the  night,  without  any  alternation  of  day  and  night  work.  . 
.  .  .  .  We  do  not  find  any  difference  in  the  health  of  those 
who  work  regularly  by  night  and  those  who  work  by  day,  and 
probably  people  can  sleep  better  if  they  have  the  same  period 

of  rest  than  if  it  is  changed About  20  of  the  boys 

under  the  age  of  18  work  in  the  night  sets We 

could  not  well  do  without  lads  under  18  working  by  night. 
The  objection  would  be  the  increase  in  the  cost  of  production. 
.  .  .  .  Skilled  hands  and  the  heads  in  every  department 
are  difficult  to  get,  but  of  lads  we  could  get  any  number.  . 
.  .  .  But  from  the  small  proportion  of  boys  that  we  employ, 
the  subject  (?.«.,  of  restrictions  on  night  work)  Ls  of  little  im- 
portance or  interest  to  us."^ 

Mr.  J.  Ellis,  one  of  the  firm  of  Messi-s,  John  Brown  &;  Co., 
steel  and  iron  works,  employing  about  SOOO  men  and  boys,  part 
of  whose  operations,  namely,  iron  and  heavier  steel  work,  goes 
on  night  and  day  by  relays,  states  "  that  in  the  heavier  steel 
work  one  or  two  boys  are  employed  to  a  score  or  two  men." 
Their  concern  employs  upwards  of  500  boys  under  18,  of  whom 
about  i  or  170  are  under  the  age  of  13.     With  reference  to  the 

relief  or  cessation  beyond  2  or,  at  most,  3  breaks  of  half-an-hour  each  for  meals."  In 
some  mills,  where  regular  night-work  has  been  entirely  given  up,  over-work  goes  on 
to  a  terrible  extent,  "and  that  often  in  the  dirtiest,  and  in  the  hottest,  and  in  the 
most  monotonous  of  the  various  processes."  ("  Ch.  Employment  Comm.  Eeport 
IV    1865,"  p.  xxxviii  and  xxxix.)  i  Fourth  Report,  &c.,  1865,  70,  p.  xvL 


246  Capitalist  Production, 

proposed  alteration  of  the  law,  Mr  Ellis  says  :  "  I  do  not  think 
it  would  be  very  objectionable  to  require  that  no  person  under 
the  age  of  18  should  work  more  than  12  hours  in  the  24.  But 
we  do  not  think  that  any  line  could  be  drawn  over  the  age  of 
12,  at  which  boys  could  be  dispensed  with  for  night  work.  But 
we  would  sooner  be  prevented  from  employing  boys  under  the 
age  of  13,  or  even  so  high  as  14,  at  all,  than  not  be  allowed  to 
employ  boys  that  we  do  have  at  night.  Those  boys  who 
work  in  the  day  sets  must  take  their  turn  in  the  night  sets  also, 
because  the  men  could  not  work  in  tlie  night  sets  only ;   it 

would  ruin  their  health We  think,  however,  that 

night  work  in  alternate  weeks  is  no  harm.  (Messrs.  Nay  lor  & 
Vickers,  on  the  other  hand,  in  conformity  with  the  interest  of 
their  business,  considered  that  periodically  changed  night-labour 
might  possibly  do  more  harm  than  continual  night-labour.)  We 
find  the  men  who  do  it,  as  well  as  the  others  who  do  other 

work  only  by  day Our   objections   to  not 

allowing  boys  under  18  to  work  at  night,  would  be  on  account 
of  the  increase  of  expense,  but  this  is  the  only  reason.  (What 
cynical  naivete !)  We  think  that  the  increase  would  be  more 
than  the  trade,  with  due  regard  to  its  being  successfully  carried 
out,  could  fairly  bear.  (What  mealy-mouthed  phraseology  I) 
Labour  is  scarce  heie,  and  might  fall  short  if  there  were  such 
a  regulation."  {i.e.,  Ellis  Brown  &  Co.  might  fall  into  the  fatal 
j)erplexity  of  being  obliged  to  pay  labour-power  its  full  value.)i 
The  "  Cyclops  Steel  and  Iron  Works,"  of  Messrs.  Cammell  & 
Co.,  are  conducted  on  the  same  large  scale  as  those  of  the  above 
mentioned  John  Brown  &  Co.  The  managing  director  had 
handed  in  his  evidence  to  the  Government  Commissioner,  Mr. 
White,  in  writing.  Later  he  found  it  convenient  to  suppress 
the  MS.  when  it  had  been  returned  to  him  for  revision.  Mr. 
White,  however,  has  a  good  memory.  He  remembered  quite 
clearly  that  for  the  Messrs.  Cyclops  the  forbidding  of  the  night- 
labour  of  children  and  young  persons  "  would  be  impossible,  it 
would  be  tantamount  to  stopping  their  works,"  and  yet  their 
business  employs  little  more  than  6  %  ^^  ^^7^  under  18,  and 
less  than  1  %  under  13.2 

1 1,  c.  80,  p.  xvi.  2  1.  c.  82,  p.  xviL 


The   Working  Day.  247 

On  the  same  subject  Mr.  E.  F.  Sanderson,  of  the  firm  of 
Sanderson,  Bros.,  &  Co.,  steel  rolling-mills  and  forges,  AtterclifFe, 
says :  "  Great  difficulty  would  be  caused  by  preventing  boys 
under  18  from  workinor  at  niorht.  The  chief  would  be  the  in- 
crease  of  cost  from  employing  men  instead  of  boys.  I  cannot 
say  what  this  would  be,  but  probably  it  would  not  be  enough 
to  enable  the  manufacturers  to  raise  the  price  of  steel,  and  con- 
sequently it  would  fall  on  them,  as  of  course  the  men  (what 
queer-headed  folk ! )  would  refuse  to  pay  it."  Mr.  San- 
derson does  not  know  how  much  he  pays  the  children,  but 
"  perhaps  the  younger  boys  get  from  4s.  to  5s.  a  week.  .  .  . 
The  boys'  work  is  of  a  kind  for  which  the  strength  of  the  boys 
is  generally  ('  generally,'  of  course  not  always)  quite  sufficient, 
and  consequently  there  would  be  no  gain  in  the  greater  strength 
of  the  men  to  counterbalance  the  loss,  or  it  would  be  only  in 
the  few  cases  in  which  the  metal  is  heavy.  The  men  would 
not  like  so  well  not  to  have  boys  under  them,  as  men  would  be 
less  obedient.  Besides,  boys  must  begin  young  to  learn  the 
trade.  Leaving  day  work  alone  open  to  boys  would  not  answer 
this  purpose."  And  why  not  ?  Why  could  not  boys  learn 
their  handicraft  in  the  day-time  ?  Your  reason  ?  "  Owing  to 
the  men  working  days  and  nights  in  alternate  weeks,  the  men 
would  be  separated  half  the  time  from  their  boys,  and  would 
lose  half  the  profit  which  they  make  from  them.  The  training 
which  they  give  to  an  apprentice  is  considered  as  part  of  the 
return  for  the  boys'  labour,  and  thus  enables  the  men  to  get  it 
at  a  cheaper  rate.  Each  man  would  want  half  of  this  profit." 
In  other  words,  Messrs.  Sanderson  would  have  to  pay  part  of 
the  wages  of  the  adult  men  out  of  their  own  pockets  instead  of 
by  the  night  work  of  the  boys.  Messrs.  Sanderson's  profit 
would  thus  fall  to  some  extent,  and  this  is  the  good  Sandersonian 
reason  why  boys  cannot  learn  their  handicraft  in  the  day.^  In 
addition  to  this,  it  would  throw  night  labour  on  those  who 
worked  instead  of  the  boys,  which  they  would  not  be  able  to 

1  In  our  reflecting  and  reasoning  age  a  man  is  not  worth  much  who  cannot  give  a 
good  reason  for  everything,  no  matter  how  bad  or  how  crazy.  Everything  in  the 
world  that  has  been  done  wrong  has  been  done  wrong  for  the  very  best  of  reasons. 
(Hegel,  1.  c,  p.  249.) 


248  Capitalist  Production. 

stand.  The  difficulties  in  fact  would  be  so  great  that  they 
would  very  likely  lead  to  the  giving  up  of  night  work  altogether, 
and  "  as  far  as  the  work  itself  is  concerned,"  says  E.  F.  Sander- 
son, "  this  would  suit  as  well,  but — "  But  Messrs.  Sanderson 
have  something  else  to  make  besides  steel.  Steel-making  is 
simply  a  pretext  for  surplus-value  making.  Tlie  smelting 
furnaces,  rolling-mills,  &c.,  the  buildings,  machinery,  iron,  coal, 
&;c.,  have  something  more  to  do  than  transform  themselves  into 
steel.  They  are  there  to  absorb  surplus-labour,  and  naturally 
absorb  more  in  24  hours  than  in  12.  In  fact  they  give,  by 
grace  of  God  and  law,  the  Sandersons  a  cheque  on  the  working 
time  of  a  certain  number  of  hands  for  all  the  24  hours  of  the 
day,  and  they  lose  their  character  as  capital,  are  therefore  a 
pure  loss  for  the  Sandersons,  as  soon  as  their  function  of 
absorbing  labour  is  interrupted.  "  But  then  there  would  be 
the  loss  from  so  much  expensive  machinery,  lying  idle  half  the 
time,  and  to  get  through  the  amount  of  work  which  we  are  able 
to  do  on  the  present  system,  we  should  have  to  double  our 
premises  and  plant,  w^hich  would  double  the  outlay."  But  why 
should  these  Sandersons  pretend  to  a  privilege  not  enjoyed  by 
the  other  capitalists  who  only  work  during  the  day,  and  whose 
buildings,  machinery,  raw  material,  therefore  lie  "  idle  "  during 
the  night  ?  E.  F.  Sanderson  answers  in  the  name  of  all  the 
Sandersons  :  "  It  is  true  that  there  is  this  loss  from  machinery 
lying  idle  in  those  manufactories  in  which  work  only  goes  on 
by  day.  But  the  use  of  furnaces  would  involve  a  further  loss 
in  our  case.  If  they  were  kept  up  there  would  be  a  waste  of 
fuel  (instead  of,  as  now,  a  waste  of  the  living  substance  of  the 
w^orkers),  and  if  they  were  not,  there  would  be  loss  of  time  in 
laying  the  fires  and  getting  the  heat  up  (whilst  the  loss  of 
sleeping  time,  even  to  children  of  8  is  a  gain  of  working 
time  for  the  Sanderson  tribe),  and  the  furnaces  themselves 
would  suffer  from  the  changes  of  temperature."  (Whilst  those 
same  furnaces  suffer  nothing  from  the  day  and  night  change  of 
labour.)^ 

1 1.  c.  85,  p.  xvii.  To  similar  tender  scruples  of  the  glass  manufacturers  that  regular 
meal  times  for  the  children  are  impossible  because  as  a  consequence  a  certain  quantity 
of  heat,  radiated  by  the  furnaces,  would  be  **a  pure  loss"  or  "wasted,"  Com- 
missioner White  makes  answer.     His  answer  is  unlike  that  of  Ure,  Senior,  &c.,  and 


The  Working  Day.  249 


SECTION  5.— THE  STRUGGLE  FOR  A  NORMAL  WORKING  DAY.  COMPULSORY 
LAWS  FOR  THE  EXTENSION  OF  THE  WORKING  DAY  FROM  THE  MIDDLE  OF 
THE  14th  TO  THE  END  OF  THE  17tH  CENTURY. 

"  What  is  a  working  day  ?  What  is  the  length  of  time 
during  which  capital  may  consume  the  labour-power  whose 
daily  value  it  buys  ?  How  far  may  the  working  day  be  ex- 
tended beyond  the  working  time  necessary  for  the  reproduction 
of  labour-power  itself  ? "  It  has  been  seen  that  to  these 
questions  capital  replies  :  the  working  day  contains  the  full  24 
hours,  with  the  deduction  of  the  few  hours  of  repose  without 
which  labour-power  absolutely  refuses  its  services  again. 
Hence  it  is  self-evident  that  the  labourer  is  nothing  else,  his 
whole  life  through,  than  labour-power,  that  therefore  all  his 
disposable  time  is  by  nature  and  law  labour-time,  to  be  devoted 
to  the  self-expansion  of  capital.  Time  for  education,  for 
intellectual  development,  for  the  fulfilling  of  social  functions 
and  for  social  intercourse,  for  the  free-play  of  his  bodily  and 
mental  activity,  even  the  rest  time  of  Sunday  (and  that  in  a 

their  puny  German  plagiarists  ^  la  Eoscher  who  are  touched  by  the  "abstinence,'' 
"  self-denial,"  "saving,"  of  the  capitalists  in  the  expenditure  of  their  gold,  and  by  their 
Timur-Tamerlanish  prodigality  of  human  life  !  "A  certain  amount  of  heat  beyond 
what  is  usual  at  present  might  also  be  going  to  waste,  if  meal  times  were  secured  in 
these  cases,  but  it  seems  likely  not  equal  in  money-value  to  the  waste  of  animal 
power  now  going  on  in  glass-houses  throughout  the  kingdom  from  growing  boys  not 
having  enough  quiet  time  to  eat  their  meals  at  ease,  with  a  little  rest  afterwards  for 
digestion."  (1.  c,  p.  xlv.)  And  this  in  the  year  of  progress  1865  !  Without  con- 
sidering the  expenditure  of  strength  in  lifting  and  carrying,  such  a  child,  in  the  sheds 
where  bottle  and  flint  glass  are  made,  walks  during  the  performance  of  his  work  15-20 
miles  in  every  6  hours  !  And  the  work  often  lasts  14  or  15  hours  !  In  many  of 
these  glass  works,  as  in  the  Moscow  spinning  mills,  the  system  of  6  hours'  relays  is  in 
force.  "  During  the  working  part  of  the  week  six  hours  is  the  utmost  unbroken 
period  ever  attained  at  any  one  time  for  rest,  and  out  of  this  has  to  come  the  time 
spent  in  coming  and  going  to  and  from  work,  washing,  dressing,  and  meals,  leaving  a 
very  short  period  indeed  for  rest,  and  none  for  fresh  air  and  play,  unless  at  the  expense 
of  the  sleep  necessary  for  young  boys,  especially  at  such  hot  and  fatiguing  work.  . 
.  .  .  Even  the  short  sleep  is  obviously  liable  to  be  broken  by  a  boy  having  to  wake 
himself  if  it  is  night,  or  by  the  noise,  if  it  is  day."  Mr  White  gives  cases  where  a  boy 
worked  36  consecutive  hours  ;  others  where  boys  of  12  drudged  on  until  2  in  the  morn- 
ing, and  then  slept  in  the  works  till  5  a.m.  (3  hours !)  only  to  resume  their  work. 
"The  amount  of  work,"  say  Tremenheere  and  Tufnell,  who  drafted  the  general 
report,  "done  by  boys,  youths,  girls,  and  women,  in  the  course  of  their  daily  or 
nightly  spell  of  labour,  is  certainly  extraordinary."  (1.  c,  xliii.  and  xliv.)  Meanwhile, 
late  by  night  perhaps,  self-denying  Mr.  Glass-Capital,  primed  with  port-wine,  reels  out 
of  his  club  homeward  droning  out  idiotically,  "  Britons  never,  never  shall  be  slaves  T 


250  Capitalist  Production, 

country  of  Sabbatarians  !)^ — moonshine  !  But  in  its  blind 
unrestrainable  passion,  its  were-wolf  hunger  for  surplus-labour, 
capital  oversteps  not  only  the  moral,  but  even  the  merely 
physical  maximum  bounds  of  the  working  day.  It  usurps  the 
time  for  growth,  development,  and  healthy  maintenance  of 
the  body.  It  steals  the  time  required  for  the  consumption  of 
fresh  air  and  sunlight.  It  higgles  over  a  meal -time,  incorpor- 
ating it  where  possible  with  the  process  of  production  itself,  so 
that  food  is  given  to  the  labourer  as  to  a  mere  means  of  pro- 
duction, as  coal  is  supplied  to  the  boiler,  grease  and  oil  to  the- 
machinery.  It  reduces  the  sound  sleep  needed  for  the  resto- 
ration, reparation,  refreshment  of  the  bodily  powers  to  just  so 
many  hours  of  torpor  as  the  revival  of  an  organism,  absolutely 
exhausted,  renders  essential.  It  is  not  the  normal  maintenance 
of  the  labour-power  which  is  to  determine  the  limits  of  the 
working  day ;  it  is  the  greatest  possible  daily  expenditure  of 
labour-power,  no  matter  how  diseased,  compulsory,  and  painful 
it  may  be,  which  is  to  determine  the  limits  of  the  labourers* 
period  of  repose.  Capital  cares  nothing  for  the  length  of  life 
of  labour-power.  All  that  concerns  it  is  simply  and  solely  the 
maximum  of  labour-power,  that  can  be  rendered  fluent  in  a 
working  day.  It  attains  this  end  by  shortening  the  extent  of 
the  labourer's  life,  as  a  greedy  farmer  snatches  increased  pro- 
duce from  the  soil  by  robbing  it  of  its  fertility. 

The  capitalistic  mode  of  production  (essentially  the  pro- 
duction of  surplus- value,  the  absorption  of  surplus-labour), 
produces  thus,  with  the  extension  of  the  working  day,  not  only 
the  deterioration  of  human  labour-power  by  robbing  it  of  its 

1  In  England  even  now  occasionally  in  rural  districts  a  labourer  is  condemned  to 
imprisonment  for  desecrating  the  Sabbath,  by  working  in  his  front  garden.  The  same 
labourer  is  punished  for  breach  of  contract  if  he  remains  away  from  his  metal,  paper, 
or  glass  works  on  the  Sunday,  even  if  it  be  from  a  religious  whim.  The  orthodox 
Parliament  will  hear  nothing  of  Sabbath-breaking  if  it  occurs  in  the  process  of  ex- 
panding capital.  A  memorial  (August  1863),  in  which  the  London  day-labourers  in 
fish  and  poultry  shops  asked  for  the  abolition  of  Sunday  labour,  states  that  their  work 
lasts  for  the  first  6  days  of  the  week  on  an  average  15  hours  a-day,  and  on  Sunday 
8-10  hours.  From  this  same  memorial  we  learn  also  that  the  delicate  gourmands 
among  the  aristocratic  hypocrites  of  Exeter  Hall,  especially  encourage  this  "Sunday 
labour."  These  "  holy  ones,"  so  zealous  in  cute  curanda,  show  their  Christianity  by 
the  humility  with  which  they  bear  the  overwork,  the  privations,  and  the  hunger  of 
others.     Ohsequium  ventris  istis  {the  labourers)  pemiciosius  est. 


The   Working  Day,  251 

normal,  moral  and  physical,  conditions  of  development  and 
function.  It  produces  also  the  premature  exhaustion  and  death 
of  this  labour-power  itself.^  It  extends  the  labourer's  time  of 
production  during  a  given  period  by  shortening  his  actual  life- 
time. 

But  the  value  of  the  labour-power  includes  the  value  of  the 
commodities  necessary  for  the  reproduction  of  the  worker,  or 
for  the  keeping  up  of  the  working  class.  If  then  the  unnatural 
extension  of  the  working  day,  that  capital  necessarily  strives 
after  in  its  unmeasured  passion  for  self-expansion,  shortens  the 
length  of  life  of  the  individual  labourer,  and  therefore  the 
duration  of  his  labour-power,  the  forces  used  up  have  to  be  re- 
placed at  a  more  rapid  rate  and  the  sum  of  the  expenses  for 
the  reproduction  of  labour-power  will  be  greater ;  just  as  in  a 
machine  the  part  of  its  value  to  be  reproduced  every  day  is 
greater  the  more  rapidly  the  machine  is  worn  out.  It  would 
seem  therefore  that  the  interest  of  capital  itself  points  in  the 
direction  of  a  normal  working  day. 

The  slave-owner  buys  his  labourer  as  he  buys  his  horse.  If 
he  loses  his  slave,  he  loses  capital  that  can  only  be  restored  by 
new  outlay  in  the  slave-mart.  But  "  the  rice-grounds  of 
Georgia,  or  the  swamps  of  the  Mississippi  may  be  fatally  in- 
jurious to  the  human  constitution ;  but  the  waste  of  human 
life  which  the  cultivation  of  these  districts  necessitates,  is  not 
so  great  that  it  cannot  be  repaired  from  the  teeming  preserves 
of  Virginia  and  Kentucky.  Considerations  of  economy,  more- 
over, which,  under  a  natural  system,  afford  some  security  for 
humane  treatment  by  identifying  the  master's  interest  with 
the  slave's  preservation,  when  once  trading  in  slaves  is  practised, 
become  reasons  for  racking  to  the  uttermost  the  toil  of  the 
slave ;  for,  when  his  place  can  at  once  be  supplied  from  foreign 
preserves,  the  duration  of  his  life  becomes  a  matter  of  less 
moment  than  its  productiveness  while  it  lasts.  It  is  accord- 
ingly a  maxim  of  slave  management,  in  slave-importing 
countries,  that  the  most  effective  economy  is  that  which  takes 

1  "  We  have  given  in  our  previous  reports  the  statements  of  several  experienced 
manufacturers  to  the  effect  that  over-hours.  .  .  .  certainly  tend  prematurely  to  ex 
haust  the  working  power  of  the  men."    (1.  c.  61,  p.  xiii.) 


252  Capitalist  Proditction. 

out  of  the  human  chattel  in  the  shortest  space  of  time  the 
utmost  amount  of  exertion  it  is  capable  of  putting  forth.  It 
is  in  tropical  culture,  where  annual  profits  often  equal  the 
whole  capital  of  plantations,  that  negro  life  is  most  recklessly 
sacrificed.  It  is  the  agriculture  of  the  West  Indies,  which  has 
been  for  centuries  prolific  of  fabulous  wealth,  that  has  engulfed 
millions  of  the  African  race.  It  is  in  Cuba,  at  this  day,  whose 
revenues  are  reckoned  by  millions,  and  whose  planters  are 
princes,  that  we  see  in  the  servile  class,  the  coarsest  fare,  the 
most  exhausting  and  unremitting  toil,  and  even  the  absolute 
destruction  of  a  portion  of  its  numbers  every  year."^ 

Mntato  nomine  de  te  fabula  narratur.  For  slave-trade 
read  labour-market,  for  Kentucky  and  Virginia,  Ireland  and 
the  agricultural  districts  of  England,  Scotland,  and  Wales, 
for  Africa,  Germany.  We  heard  how  over-work  thinned  the 
ranks  of  the  bakers  in  London.  Nevertheless,  the  London 
labour-market  is  always  over-stocked  with  German  and  other 
candidates  for  death  in  the  bakeries.  Pottery,  as  we  saw,  is 
one  of  the  shortest-lived  industries.  Is  there  any  want  there- 
fore of  potters  ?  Josiah  Wedgwood,  the  inventor  of  modem 
pottery,  himself  originally  a  common  workman,  said  in  1785 
before  the  House  of  Commons  that  the  whole  trade  employed 
from  15,000  to  20,000  people.^  In  the  year  1861  the  population 
alone  of  the  town  centres  of  this  industry  in  Great  Britain 
numbered  101,802.  "  The  cotton  trade  has  existed  for  ninety 
years.  ...  It  has  existed  for  three  generations  of  the  English 
race,  and  I  believe  I  may  safely  say  that  during  that  period  it 
has  destroyed  nine  generations  of  factory  operatives."^ 

No  doubt  in  certain  epochs  of  feverish  activity  the  labour- 
market  shows  significant  gaps.  In  1834,  e.g.  But  then  the 
manufacturers  proposed  to  the  Poor  Law  Commissioners  that 
they  should  send  the  "  surplus-population  "  of  the  agricultural 
districts  to  the  noi'th,  with  the  explanation  "  that  the  manu- 
facturers would  absorb  and  use  it  up."*  "  Agents  were  ap- 
pointed with  the  consent  of  the  Poor  Law  Commissioners.  .  .  . 

1  Cairnes,  "  The  Slave  Power,"  p.  110,  111. 

2  John  Ward  :  "  History  of  the  Borough  of  Stoke-upon-Trent,"  London,  1843,  p.  42. 
8  Ferrand's  Speech  in  the  House  of  Commons,  27th  April,  1863. 

4  "  Those  were  the  very  words  used  by  the  cotton  manufacturers,"  L  c. 


The  Working  Day.  253 

An  office  was  set  up  in  Manchester,  to  which  lists  were  sent  of 
those  woi'kpeople  in  the  agricultural  districts  wanting  employ- 
ment, and  their  names  were  registered  in  books.  The  manu- 
facturers attended  at  these  offices,  and  selected  such  persons  as 
they  chose ;  when  they  had  selected  such  persons  as  their 
'  wants  required,*  they  gave  instructions  to  have  them  for- 
warded to  Manchester,  and  they  were  sent,  ticketed  like  bales 
of  goods,  by  canals,  or  with  carriers,  others  tramping  on  the 
road,  and  many  of  them  were  found  on  the  way  lost  and  half- 
starved.  This  system  had  grown  up  into  a  regular  trade. 
This  House  will  hardly  believe  it,  but  I  tell  them,  that  this 
traffic  in  human  flesh  was  as  well  kept  up,  they  were  in  effect 
as  regularly  sold  to  these  [Manchester]  manufacturers  as  slaves 

are  sold  to  the  cotton-grower  in  the  United  States In 

1860,  *  the  cotton  trade  was  at  its  zenith.'  ....  The  manu- 
facturers again  found  that  they  were  short  of  hands.  .  .  .  They 
applied  to  the  '  flesh  agents,'  as  they  are  called.  Those  agents 
sent  to  the  southern  downs  of  England,  to  the  pastures  of  Dor- 
setshire, to  the  glades  of  Devonshire,  to  the  people  tending 
kine  in  Wiltshire,  but  they  sought  in  vain.  The  surplus- 
population  was  '  absorbed.' "  The  "  Bury  Guardian  "  said,  on 
the  completion  of  the  French  treaty,  that  "  10,000  additional 
hands  could  be  absorbed  by  Lancashire,  and  that  80,000  or 
40,000  will  be  needed."  After  the  "  flesh  agents  and  sub- 
ao^ents  "  had  in  vain  souorht  throuo^h  the  ao^ricultural  districts, 
"  a  deputation  came  up  to  London,  and  waited  on  the  right  hon. 
gentleman  [Mr.  Villiers,  President  of  the  Poor  Law  Board]  with 
a  view  of  obtaining  poor  children  from  certain  union  houses 
for  the  mills  of  Lancashire."^ 

1 1.  c.  Mr.  Villiers,  despite  the  best  of  intentions  on  his  part,  was  "  legally"  obliged 
to  refuse  the  requests  of  the  manufacturers.  These  gentlemen,  however,  attained 
their  end  through  the  obliging  nature  of  the  local  poor  law  boards.  Mr.  A.  Redgrave, 
Inspector  of  Factories,  asserts  that  this  time  the  system  under  which  orphans  and 
pauper  children  were  treated  "legally"  as  apprentices  "  was  not  accompanied  with 
the  old  abuses  "  (on  these  "abuses"  see  Engels,  1.  c),  although  in  one  case  there 
certainly  was  "  abuse  of  this  system  in  respect  to  a  number  of  girls  and  young  women 
brought  from  the  agricultui-al  districts  of  Scotland  into  Lancashire  and  Cheshire." 
Under  this  system  the  manufacturer  entered  into  a  contract  with  the  workhouse 
authorities  for  a  certain  period.  He  fed,  clothed,  and  lodged  the  children,  and  gave 
them  a  small  allowance  of  money.  A  remark  of  Mr.  Redgrave  to  be  quoted  directly 
seems  strange,  especially  if  we  consider  that  even  among  the  years  of  prosperity  of 


2  54  Capitalist  Production. 

What  experience  shows  to  the  capitalist  generallj^  is  a  con- 
stant excess  of  population,  Le.,  an  excess  in  relation  to  the 
momentary  requirements  of  surplus-labour-absorbing  capital, 
although  this  excess  is  made  up  of  generations  of  human  beings 
stunted,  short-lived,  swiftly  replacing  each  other,  plucked,  so 
to  say,  before  maturity.^  And,  indeed,  experience  shows  to  the 
intelligent  observer  with  what  swiftness  and  grip  the  capitalist 
mode  of  production,  dating,  historically  speaking,  only  from 
yesterday,  has  seized  the  vital  power  of  the  people  by  the  very 
root — shows  how  the  degeneration  of  the  industrial  population 
is  only  retarded  by  the  constant  absorption  of  primitive  and 
physically  uncorrupted  elements  from  the  country — shows  how 
even  the  country  labourers,  in  spite  of  fresh  air  and  the  principle 
of  natural  selection,  that  works  so  powerfully  amongst  them, 

the  English  cotton  trade,  the  year  1860  stands  unparalleled,  and  that,  besides,  wages 
were  exceptionally  high.  For  this  extraordinary  demand  for  work  had  to  contend 
with  the  depopulation  of  Ireland,  with  unexampled  emigration  from  the  English  and 
Scotch  agricultural  districts  to  Australia  and  America,  with  an  actual  diminution  of 
the  population  in  some  of  the  English  agricultural  districts,  in  consequence  partly  of 
an  actual  breakdown  of  the  vital  force  of  the  labourers,  partly  of  the  already  effected 
dispersion  of  the  disposable  population  through  the  dealers  in  human  flesh.  Despite 
all  this  Mr.  Eedgrave  says  :  "  This  kind  of  labour,  however,  would  only  be  sought 
after  when  none  other  could  be  procured,  for  it  is  a  high-priced  labour.  The  ordinary 
wages  of  a  boy  of  13  would  be  about  4s.  per  week,  but  to  lodge,  to  clothe,  to  feed,  and  to 
provide  medical  attendance  and  proper  superintendence  for  50  or  100  of  these  boys,  and 
to  set  aside  some  remuneration  for  them,  could  not  be  accomplished  for  4s.  a-head  per 
week."  (Report  of  the  Inspector  of  Factories  for  30th  April,  1860,  p.  27.)  Mr.  Red- 
grave forgets  to  tell  us  how  the  labourer  himself  can  do  all  this  for  his  children  out 
of  their  4s.  a-week  wages,  when  the  manufacturer  cannot  do  it  for  the  50  or  100 
children  lodged,  boarded,  superintended  all  together.  To  guard  against  false  con- 
clusions from  the  text,  I  ought  here  to  remark  that  the  English  cotton  industry,  since 
it  was  placed  under  the  Factory  Act  of  1850  with  its  regulations  of  labour-time,  &c., 
must  be  regarded  as  the  model  industry  of  England.  The  English  cotton  operative  is 
in  every  respect  better  off  than  his  continental  companion  in  misery.  "  The  Prussian 
factory  operative  labours  at  least  ten  hours  per  week  more  than  his  English  competi- 
tor, and  if  employed  at  his  own  loom  in  his  own  house,  his  labour  is  not  restricted 
to  even  those  additional  hours."  ("  Rep.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  Oct.  1853,  p.  103.)  Red- 
grave, the  Factory  Inspector  mentioned  above,  after  the  Industrial  Exhibition  in  1851, 
travelled  on  the  Continent,  especially  in  France  and  Germany,  for  the  purpose  of 
inquiring  into  the  conditions  of  the  factories.  Of  the  Prussian  operative  he  says : 
*'  He  receives  a  remuneration  sufficient  to  procure  the  simple  fare,  and  to  supply  the 

slender  comforts  to  which  he  has  been  accustomed he  lives  upon  his  coarse 

fare,  and  works  hard,  wherein  his  position  is  subordinate  to  that  of  the  English  oj^era- 
tive."    ("  Rep.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  Oct.,  1853,  p.  85.) 

1  The  overworked  "  die  off  with  strange  rapidity ;  but  the  places  of  those  who 
perish  are  instantly  filled,  and  a  frequent  change  of  persons  makes  no  alteration  in  the 
scene."  ("Endand  and  America."  London,  1833,  vol.  I,  p.  55.    Bv  E.  G.  Wakefield.) 


The   Working  Day,  255  ' 

and  only  permits  the  survival  of  the  strongest,  are  already  be- 
ginning to  die  off.^  Capital  that  has  such  good  reasons  for 
denying  the  sufferings  of  the  legions  of  workers  that  surround 
it,  is  in  practice  moved  as  much  and  as  little  by  the  sight  of 
the  coming  degradation  and  final  depopulation  of  the  human 
race,  as  by  the  probable  fall  of  the  earth  into  the  sun.  In  every 
stock-jobbing  swindle  every  one  knows  that  some  time  or  other 
the  crash  must  come,  but  every  one  hopes  that  it  may  fall  on 
the  head  of  his  neighbour,  after  he  himself  has  caught  the 
shower  of  gold  and  placed  it  in  safety.  Apres  moi  le  deluge  ! 
is  the  watchword  of  every  capitalist  and  of  every  capitalist 
nation.  Hence  Capital  is  reckless  of  the  health  or  length  of 
life  of  the  labourer,  unless  under  compulsion  from  society.^  To 
the  outcry  as  to  the  physical  and  mental  degradation,  the  pre- 
mature death,  the  torture  of  overwork,  it  answers  :  Ought  these 
to  trouble  us  since  they  increase  our  profits  ?  But  looking  at 
things  as  a  whole,  all  this  does  not,  indeed,  depend  on  the  good 
or  ill  will  of  the  individual  capitalist.  Free  competition  brings 
out  the  inherent  laws  of  capitalist  production,  in  the  shape  of 
external  coercive  laws  having  power  over  every  individual 
capitalist.^ 

1  See  "  Public  Health.  Sixth  Report  of  the  Medical  Officer  of  the  Privy  Council, 
1863."  Published  in  London  1864.  This  report  deals  especially  with  the  agricultural 
labourers.  "  Sutherland  ...  is  commonly  represented  as  a  highly  improved  county 
.  .  .  but  .  .  .  recent  inquiry  has  discovered  that  even  there,  in  districts  once  famous 
for  fine  men  and  gallant  soldiers,  the  inhabitants  have  degenerated  into  a  meagre  and 
stunted  race.  In  the  healthiest  situations,  on  hill  sides  fronting  the  sea,  the  faces  of 
their  famished  children  are  as  pale  as  they  could  be  in  the  foul  atmosphere  of  a 
London  alley."  (W.  T.  Thornton.  "Over-population  and  its  remedy."  1.  c,  p.  74, 
75.)  They  resemble  in  fact  the  30,000  ** gallant  Highlanders"  whom  Glasgow  pigs 
together  in  its  wynds  and  closes,  with  prostitutes  and  thieves. 

2  "But  though  the  health  of  a  population  is  so  important  a  fact  of  the  national 
capital,  we  are  afraid  it  must  be  said  that  the  class  of  employers  of  labour  have  not 
been  the  most  forward  to  guard  and  cherish  this  treasure.  .  .  .  The  consideration  of 
the  health  of  the  operatives  was  forced  upon  the  millowners.  ("Times,"  November 
5th,  1861.)  "The  men  of  the  West  Riding  became  the  clothiers  of  mankind  .... 
the  health  of  the  workpeople  was  sacrificed,  and  the  race  in  a  few  generations  must 
have  degenerated.  But  a  reaction  set  in.  Lord  Shaftesbury's  Bill  limited  the  hours 
of  children's  labour,"  &c.     ("  Report  of  the  Registrar-General,"  for  October  1861.) 

3  We,  therefore,  find,  e.g.,  that  in  the  beginning  of  1863,  26  firms  owning  extensive 
potteries  in  Staffordshire,  amongst  others,  Josiah  "Wedgwood,  &  Sons'  petition  in  a 
memorial  for  "  some  legislative  enactment."  Competition  with  other  capitalists  per- 
mits them  no  voluntary  limitation  of  working-time  for  children,  &c.  "  Much  as  we 
deplore  the  evils  before  mentioned,  it  would  not  be  possible  to  prevent  them  by  any 


256  Capitalist  Production, 

The  establishment  of  a  normal  working  day  is  the  result  of 
centuries  of  struggle  between  capitalist  and  labourer.  The 
history  of  this  sti'uggle  shows  two  opposed  tendencies.  Com- 
pare, e.g.y  the  English  factory  legislation  of  our  time  with  the 
English  Labour  Statutes  from  the  14th  century  to  well  into 
the  middle  of  the  18th.^  Whilst  the  modern  Factory  Acts  com- 
pulsorily  shartened  the  working-day,  the  earlier  statutes  tried 
to  lengthen  it  by  compulsion.  Of  course  the  pretensions  of 
capital  in  embryo — when,  beginning  to  grow,  it  secures  the 
right  of  absorbing  a  quantum  sufficit  of  surplus-labour,  not 
merely  by  the  force  of  economic  relations,  but  by  the  help  of 
the  State — appear  very  modest  when  put  face  to  face  with  the 
concessions  that,  growling  and  struggling,  it  has  to  make  in  its 
adult  condition.  It  takes  centuries  ere  the  "  free  "  labourer, 
thanks  to  the  development  of  capitalistic  production,  agrees, 
i.e.,  is  compelled  by  social  conditions,  to  sell  the  whole  of  his 
active  life,  his  very  capacity  for  work,  for  the  price  of  the 
necessaries  of  life,  his  birthright  for  a  mess  of  pottage.  Hence 
it  is  natural  that  the  lengthening  of  the  working  day,  which 
capital,  from  the  middle  of  the  14th  to  the  end  of  the  17th 
century,  tries  to  impose  by  State-measures  on  adult  labourers, 
approximately  coincides  with  the  shortening  of  the  working 
day  which,  in  the  second  half  of  the  19th  century,  has  here  and 
there  been  effected  by  the  State  to  prevent  the  coining  of 
children's  blood  into  capital.  That  which  to-day,  e.g.,  in  the 
State  of  Massachusetts,  until  recently  the  freest  State  of  the 
North-American  Republic,  has  been  proclaimed  as  the  statutory 

scheme  of  agreement  between  the  manufacturers.  .  .  .  Taking  all  these  points  into 
consideration,  we  have  come  to  the  convi..tion  that  some  legislative  enactment  is 
wanted."  ("  Children's  Employment  Comm."  Rep.  1.,  1863,  p.  322.)  Most  recently  a 
much  more  striking  example  offers.  The  rise  in  the  price  of  cotton  during  a  period 
of  feverish  activity,  had  induced  the  manufacturers  in  Blackburn  to  shorten,  by 
mutual  consent,  the  working-time  in  their  mills  during  a  certain  fixed  period.  This 
period  terminated  about  the  end  of  November,  1871.  Meanwhile,  the  wealthier 
manufacturers,  who  combined  spinning  with  weaving,  used  the  diminution  of  produc- 
tion resulting  from  this  agreement,  to  extend  their  own  business  and  thus  to  make 
great  profits  at  the  expense  of  the  small  employers.  The  latter  thereupon  turned  in 
their  extremity  to  the  operatives,  urged  them  earnestly  to  agitate  for  the  9  hours' 
system,  and  promised  contributions  in  money  to  this  end. 

1  The  Labour  Statutes,  the  like  of  which  were  enacted  at  the  same  time  in  France, 
the  Netherlands,  and  elsewhere,  were  first  formally  repealed  in  England  in  1813,  long 
after  the  changes  in  methods  of  production  had  rendered  them  obsolete. 


The   Working  Day,  257 

limit  of  the  labour  of  children  under  12,  was  in  England,  even 
in  the  middle  of  the  I7th  century,  the  normal  working-day  of 
able-bodied  artizans,  robust  labourers,  athletic  blacksmiths/ 

The  first  "  Statute  of  Labourers  "  (23  Edward  III,  1349) 
found  its  immediate  pretext  (not  its  cause,  for  legislation  of 
this  kind  lasts  centuries  after  the  pretext  for  it  has  disappeared) 
in  the  great  plague  that  decimated  the  people,  so  that,  as  a  Tory 
writer  says,  "  The  difficulty  of  getting  men  to  work  on  reason- 
able terms  {i.e.,  at  a  price  that  left  their  employers  a  reasonable 
quantity  of  surplus-labour)  grew  to  such  a  height  as  to  be  quite 
intolerable."^  Reasonable  wages  were,  therefore,  fixed  by  law 
as  well  as  the  limits  of  the  working  day.  The  latter  point,  the 
only  one  that  here  interests  us,  is  repeated  in  the  Statute  of 
1496  (Henry  YIII.).  The  working  day  for  all  artificers  and 
field  labourers  from  March  to  September  ought,  according  to 
this  statute  (which,  however,  could  not  be  enforced),  to  last  from 
5  in  the  morning  to  between  7  and  8  in  the  evening.  But  the 
meal  times  consist  of  1  hour  for  breakfast,  1 J  hours  for  dinner, 
and  \  an  hour  for  "  noon-meate,"  i.e.,  exactly  twice  as  much  as 
under  the  factory  acts  now  in  force.^     In  winter,  work  was  to 

1  "No  child  under  12  years  of  age  shall  be  employed  in  any  manufacturing  estab- 
lishment more  than  10  hours  in  one  day."  General  Statutes  of  Massachusetts,  G3, 
ch.  12.  (The  various  Statutes  were  passed  between  1836  and  1858.)  "Labour  per- 
formed during  a  period  of  10  hours  on  any  day  in  all  cotton,  woollen,  silk,  pa])er, 
glass,  and  flax  factories,  or  in  manufactories  of  iron  and  brass,  shall  be  considered  a 
legal  day's  labour.  And  be  it  enacted,  that  hereafter  no  minor  engaged  in  any  factory 
shall  be  holden  or  required  to  work  more  than  10  hours  in  any  day,  or  60  hoars  in  any 
week  ;  and  that  hereafter  no  minor  shall  be  admitted  as  a  worker  under  the  age  of 
10  years  in  any  factory  within  this  State. "  State  of  New  Jersey.  An  Act  to  limit 
the  hours  of  labour,  &c.,  61  and  62.  (Law  of  11th  March,  1855.)  "  No  minor  who  has 
attained  the  age  of  12  years,  and  is  under  the  age  of  15  years,  shall  be  emi)loyed  in 
any  manufacturing  establishment  more  than  11  hours  in  any  one  day,  nor  before  5 
o'clock  in  the  morning,  nor  after  7.30  in  the  evening."  ("Kevised  Statutes  of  the 
State  of  Rhode  Island,"  &c.,  ch.  39,  §  23,  1st  July,  1857.) 

2  "  Sophisms  of  Free  Trade."  7th  Ed.  London,  1850.  p.  205.  9th  Ed.,  p.  253.  This 
same  Tory,  moreover,  admits  that  "  Acts  of  Parliament  regulating  wages,  but  against 
the  labourer  and  in  favour  of  the  master,  lasted  for  the  long  period  of  464  years. 
Population  grew.  These  laws  were  then  found,  and  really  became,  unnecessary  and 
burdensome."    (h  c,  p.  206.) 

3  In  reference  to  this  statute,  J.  Wade  with  truth  remarks  :  *'  From  the  statement 
above  (i.e.,  with  regard  to  the  statute)  it  appears  that  in  1496  the  diet  was  considered 
equivalent  to  one  third  of  the  income  of  an  artificer  and  one-half  the  income  of  a 
labourer,  which  indicates  a  greater  degree  of  independence  among  the  working  classes 
than  prevails  at  present ;  for  the  board,  both  of  labourers  and  artificers,  would  now 

R 


258  Capitalist  Production. 

last  from  5  in  the  morning  until  dark,  with  the  same  intervals. 
A  statute  of  Elizabeth  of  1562  leaves  the  length  of  the  work- 
ing day  for  all  labourers  "  hired  for  daily  or  weekly  wage  "  un- 
touched, but  aims  at  limiting  the  intervals  to  21-  hours  in  the 
summer,  or  to  2  in  the  winter.  Dinner  is  only  to  last  1  hour, 
and  the  "  afternoon-sleep  of  half  an  hour  "  is  only  allowed 
between  the  middle  of  May  and  the  middle  of  August.  For 
every  hour  of  absence  Id.  is  to  be  subtracted  from  the  wage. 
In  practice,  however,  the  conditions  were  much  more  favourable 
to  the  labourers  than  in  the  statute-book.  William  Petty,  the 
father  of  political  economj^,  and  to  some  extent  the  founder  of 
Statistics,  says  in  a  work  that  he  published  in  the  last  third  of 
the  17th  century:  "Labouring-men  (then  meaning  field-labourers) 
work  10  hours  per  diem,  and  make  20  meals  per  week,  viz.,  3 
a  day  for  working  days,  and  2  on  Sundays  ;  whereby  it  is  plain, 
that  if  they  could  fast  on  Fryday  nights,  and  dine  in  one  hour 
and  an  half,  whereas  they  take  two,  from  eleven  to  one;  thereby 
this  working  h  more,  and  spending  ^V  less,  the  above-men- 
tioned (tax)  might  be  raised."^  Was  not  Dr.  Andrew  Ure  right 
in  crying  down  the  12  hours'  bill  of  1833  as  a  retrogression  to 
the  times  of  the  dark  ages  ?  It  is  true,  these  regulations  con- 
tained in  the  statute  mentioned  by  Petty,  apply  also  to  ap- 
prentices. But  the  condition  of  child-labour,  even  at  the  end 
of  the' 17th  century,  is  seen  from  the  following  complaint: 
"  'Tis  not  their  practice  (in  Germany)  as  with  us  in  this  king- 
dom, to  bind  an  apprentice  for  seven  years  ;  three  or  four  is 
their  common  standard :  and  the  reason  is,  because  they  are 
educated  from  their  cradle  to  something  of  employment,  which 
renders  them  the  more  apt  and  docile,  and  consequently  the  more 
capable  of  attaining  to  a  ripeness  and  quicker  proficiency  in 
business.  Whereas  our  youth,  here  in  England,  being  bred  to 
nothing  before  they  come  to  be  apprentices,  make  a  very  slow 

be  reckoned  at  a  much  higher  proportion  of  their  wages,"  (J.  Wade,  "  History  of  the 
Middle  and  Working  Classes,"  p.  24,  25,  and  577.)  The  opinion  that  this  difference  is 
due  to  the  difference  in  the  price-relations  between  food  and  clothing  then  and  now 
is  refuted  by  the  most  cursory  glance  at  "  Chronicon  Pretiosum,  &c."  By  Bishop 
Fleetwood.     1st  Ed.,  London,  1707;  2d  Ed.,  London,  1745. 

iW.  Petty,  "Political  Anatomy  of  Ireland,  Verbum  Sapienti,"  1672,  Ed.  1G91, 
p.  10. 


The   Working  Day.  259" 

progress  and  require  mucli  longer  time  wherein  to  reach  the 
perfection  of  accomplished  artists."^ 

Still,  during  the  greater  part  of  the  18th  century,  up  to  the 
epoch  of  Modern  Industry  and  machinism,  capital  in  England 
had  not  succeeded  in  seizing  for  itself,  by  the  payment  of  the 
weekly  value  of  labour-power,  the  whole  week  of  the  labourer 
with  the  exception,  however,  of  the  agricultural  labourers. 
The  fact  that  they  could  live  for  a  whole  week  on  the  wage  of 
four  days,  did  not  appear  to  the  labourers  a  sufficient  reason 
that  they  should  work  the  other  two  days  for  the  capitalist. 
One  party  of  English  economists,  in  the  interest  of  capita],  de- 
nounces this  obstinacy  in  the  most  violent  manner,  another 
party  defends  the  labourers.  Let  us  listen,  e.g.,  to  the  contest 
between  Postlethwayt  whose  Dictionary  of  Trade  then  had  the 
same  reputation  as  the  kindred  works  of  M'Culloch  and 
M'Gregor  to-day,  and  the  author  (already  quoted)  of  th6 
"  Essay  on  Trade  and  Commerce." 

1  "A  Discourse  on  the  necessity  of  encouraging  Mechanick  Industry,"  London^ 
1689,  p.  13.  Macaulay,  who  has  falsified  English  history  in  the  interest  of  the  Whigu 
and  the  bourgeoisie,  declares  as  follows :  "  The  practice  of  setting  children  prematurely 
to  work  ....  prevailed  in  the  17th  century  to  an  extent  which,  when  compared 
with  the  extent  of  the  manufacturing  system,  seems  almost  incredible.  At  Norwich, 
the  chief  seat  of  the  clothing  trade,  a  little  creature  of  six  years  old  was  thought  fit 
for  labour.  Several  writers  of  that  time,  and  among  them  some  who  were  considered 
as  eminently  benevolent,  mention  with  exultation  the  fact  that  in  that  single  city, 
boys  and  girls  of  very  tender  age  create  wealth  exceeding  what  was  necessary  for 
their  own  subsistence  by  twelve  thousand  pounds  a  year.  The  more  carefully  we 
examine  the  history  of  the  past,  the  more  reason  shall  we  find  to  dissent  from  those 

who  imagine  that  our  age  has  been  fruitful  of  new  social  evils That  which  is 

new  is  the  intelligence  and  the  humanity  which  remedies  them."  ("  History  of  Eng 
land,"  vol.  L,  p.  419.)  Macaulay  might  have  reported  further  that  "extremely 
well-disposed  "  amis  c^w  commerce  in  the  17th  century,  narrate  with  "exultation" 
how  in  a  poorhouse  in  Holland  a  child  of  four  was  employed,  and  that  this  example 
of  '■^vertu  mise  en  pratique  "  passes  muster  in  all  the  humanitarian  works,  cu  la  Macau- 
lay, to  the  time  of  Adam  Smith.  It  is  true  that  with  the  substitution  of  manufacture 
for  handicrafts,  traces  of  the  exploitation  of  children  begin  to  appear.  This  exploitation 
existed  always  to  a  certain  extent  among  peasants,  and  was  the  more  developed,  the 
heavier  the  yoke  pressing  on  the  husbandman.  The  tendency  of  capital  is  there  un- 
mistakably ;  but  the  facts  themselves  are  still  as  isolated  as  the  phenomena  of  two- 
headed  children.  Hence  they  were  noted  "with  exultation"  as  especially  worthy 
of  remark  and  as  wonders  by  the  far-seeing  "  amis  <itt  commerce, "  and  recommended  as 
models  for  their  own  time  and  for  posterity.  This  same  Scotch  sycophant  and  fine 
talker,  Macaulay,  says  :  "  We  hear  to-day  only  of  retrogression  and  see  only  progress." 
What  eyes,  and  especially  what  ears  ! 

2  Among  the  accusers  of  the  workpeople,  the  most  angry  is  the  anonymous  author 
quoted  in  the  text  of  "  An  Essay  on  trade  and  commerce,  containing  observations  on 


26o  Capitalist  Productton. 

Postlethwayt  sa3^s  among  other  things  :  "  We  cannot  put  an 
end  to  those  few  observations,  without  noticing  that  trite  re- 
mark in  the  mouth  of  too  many ;  that  if  the  industrious  poor 
can  obtain  enough  to  maintain  themselves  in  five  days,  they 
•will  not  work  the  whole  six.  Whence  they  infer  the  necessity 
of  even  the  necessaries  of  life  being  made  dear  by  taxes,  or  any 
other  means,  to  compel  the  working  artizan  and  manufacturer 
to  labour  the  whole  six  da3^s  in  the  week,  without  ceasing.  I 
must  beg  leave  to  differ  in  sentiment  from  those  great 
politicians,  who  contend  for  the  perpetual  slavery  of  the  work- 
ing people  of  this  kingdom  ;  they  forget  the  vulgar  adage,  all 
work  and  no  play.  Have  not  the  English  boasted  of  the  in- 
genuity and  dexterity  of  her  working  artists  and  manufacturers 
wdiich  have  heretofore  given  credit  and  reputation  to  British 
wares  in  general  ?  What  has  this  been  owing  to  ?  To  nothing 
more  probably  than  the  relaxation  of  the  working  people  in 
their  own  way.  Were  the}"  obliged  to  toil  the  year  round,  the 
whole  six  days  in  the  week,  in  a  repetition  of  the  same  work, 
might  it  not  blunt  their  ingenuity,  and  render  them  stupid  in- 
stead of  alert  and  dexterous  ;  and  might  not  our  workmen  lose 
their  reputation  instead  of  maintaining  it  by  such  eternal 
slavery  ?  .  .  .  .  And  what  sort  of  workmanship  could  we  ex- 
pect from  such  hard-driven  animals  ?  .  .  .  .  Many  of  them 
will  execute  as  much  work  in  four  days  as  a  Frenchman  will  in 
five  or  six.  But  if  Englishmen  are  to  be  eternal  drudges,  'tis 
to  be  feared  they  wull  degenerate  below  the  Frenchmen.  As 
our  people  are  famed  for  bravery  in  war,  do  we  not  say  that  it 
is  owing  to  good  English  roast  beef  and  pudding  in  their  bellies, 
as  well  as  their  constitutional  spirit  of  liberty  ?  And  why  may 
not  the  superior  ingenuity  and  dexterity  of  our  artists  and 

Taxation,  &c.,  London,  1770."  He  had  already  dealt  with  this  subject  in  his  earlier 
work :  "  Considerations  on  Taxes."  London,  1765.  On  the  same  side  follows 
Polonius  Arthur  Young,  the  unutterable  statistical  prattler.  Among  the  defenders 
of  the  working  classes  the  foremost  are  :  Jacob  Vanderlint,  in :  "  Money  answers  all 
things."  London,  1734  ;  the  Rev.  Nathaniel  Forster,  D.D.,  in  "An  Enquiry  into  the 
Causes  of  the  Present  Price  of  Provisions,"  London,  1766 ;  Dr  Price,  and  especially 
Postlethwayt,  as  well  in  the  supplement  to  his  "Universal  Dictionary  of  Trade  and 
Commerce,"  as  in  his  "Great  Britain's  Commercial  Interest  explained  and  im- 
proved." 2nd  Edition,  1755.  Tlie  facts  themselves  are  confirmed  by  many  other 
writers  of  the  time,  among  others  by  Josiah  Tucker. 


The   Working  Day,  261 

manufactures,  be  owing  to  that  freedom  and  liberty  to  direct 
themselves  in  their  own  way,  and  I  hope  we  shall  never  have 
them  deprived  of  such  privileges  and  that  good  living  from 
whence  their  ingenuity  no  less  than  their  courage  may  pro- 
ceed." ^  Thereupon  the  author  of  the  "  Essay  on  Trade  and 
Commerce  "  replies  :  "  If  the  making  of  every  seventh  day  an 
holiday  is  supposed  to  be  of  divine  institution,  as  it  implies 
the  appropriating  the  other  six  days  to  labour"  (he  means 
capital  as  we  shall  soon  see)  "  surely  it  will  not  be  thought 
cruel  to  enforce  it  ...  .  That  mankind  in  general,  are 
naturally  inclined  to  ease  and  indolence,  we  fatally  experience 
to  be  true,  from  the  conduct  of  our  manufacturing  populace, 
who  do  not  labour,  upon  an  average,  above  four  days  in  a  week, 

unless  provisions  happen  to  be  very  dear Put  all  the 

necessaries  of  the  poor  under  one  denomination ;  for  instance, 
call  them  all  wheat,  or  suppose  that  ....  the  bushel  of  wheat 
shall  cost  five  shillings  and  that  he  (a  manufacturer)  earns 
a  shilling  by  his  labour,  he  then  would  be  obliged  to  work 
five  days  only  in  a  week.  If  the  bushel  of  wheat  should  cost 
but  four  shillings,  he  would  be  obliged  to  work  but  four  days  * 
but  as  wages  in  this  kingdom  are  much  higher  in  proportion  to 
the  price  of  necessaries.  .  .  .  the  manufacturer,  who  labours  four 
days,  has  a  surplus  of  money  to  live  idle  with  the  rest  of  the 
week  ....  I  hope  I  have  said  enough  to  make  it  appear 
that  the  moderate  labour  of  six  days  in  a  week  is  no  slavery. 
Our  labouring  people  do  this,  and  to  all  appearance  are  the 
happiest  of  all  our  labouring  poor,^  but  the  Dutch  do  this  in 
manufactures,  and  appear  to  be  a  very  happy  people.  The 
French  do  so,  when  holidays  do  not  intervene.^  But  our  popu- 
lace have  adopted  a  notion,  that  as  Englishmen  they  enjoy 
a  birthright  privilege  of  being  more  free  and  independent  than 
in  any  country  in  Europe.  Now  this  idea,  as  far  as  it  may 
affect  the  bravery  of  our  troops,  may  be  of  some  use  ;  but  tho 

1  Postlethwayt,  1.  c,  "  First  Preliminary  Discourse,"  p.  14. 

2  "  An  Essay,"  &c.  He  himself  relates  on  p.  96  A^herein  the  **  happiness  "  of  the 
English  agricultural  labourer  already  in  1770  consisted.  "  Their  powers  are  always 
upon  the  stretch,  they  cannot  live  cheaper  than  they  do,  nor  work  harder." 

3  Protestantism,  by  changing  almost  all  the  traditional  holidays  into  workdays, 
plays  an  important  part  in  the  genesis  of  capital. 


262  Capitalist  Production. 

less  the  manufacturing  poor  have  of  it,  certainly  the  better  for 
themselves  and  for  the  State.  The  labouring  people  should 
never  think  themselves  independent  of  their  superiors.  .... 
It  is  extremely  dangerous  to  encourage  mobs  in  a  commercial 
state  like  ours,  where,  perhaps,  seven  parts  out  of  eight  of  the 
whole,  are  people  with  little  or  no  property.  The  cure  will 
not  be  perfect,  till  our  manufacturing  poor  are  contented  to 
labour  six  days  for  the  same  sum  which  they  now  earn  in  four 
days."  To  tliis  end,  and  for  "  extirpating  idleness,  debauchery 
and  excess,"  promoting  a  spirit  of  industry,  "  lowering  the  price 
of  labour  in  our  manufactories,  and  easing  the  lands  of  the 
heavy  burden  of  poor's  rates,"  our  "  faithful  Eckart  "  of  capital 
proposes  this  approved  device:  to  shut  up  such  labourers  as 
become  dependent  on  public  support,  in  a  word,  paupers,  in 
"  an  ideal  workhouse.^^  Such  ideal  workhouse  must  be  made  a 
"  House  of  Terror,"  and  not  an  asylum  for  the  poor, "  where  they 
are  to  be  plentifully  fed,  warmly  and  decently  clothed,  and  where 
they  do  but  little  work."^  In  this  "  House  of  Terror,"  this 
"  ideal  workhouse,  the  poor  shall  work  14  hours  in  a  day, 
allowing  proper  time  for  meals,  in  such  manner  that  there  shall 
remain  12  hours  of  neat-labour."^ 

Twelve  working  hours  daily  in  the  Ideal  Workhouse,  in  the 
"  House  of  Terror  "  of  1770  !  63  years  later,  in  1833,  when  the 
English  Parliament  reduced  the  working  day  for  children  of 
13  to  18,  in  four  branches  of  industry  to  12  full  hours,  the 
judgment  day  of  English  Industry  had  dawned  !  In  1852, 
when  Louis  Bonaparte  sought  to  secure  his  position  with  the 
bourgeoisie  by  tampering  with  the  legal  working  day,  the 
French  people  cried  out  with  one  voice  "  the  law  that  limits 
the  working  day  to  12  hours  is  the  one  good  that  has  remained 
to  us  of  the  legislation  of  the  Republic  !  "^     At  Ziirich  the  work 

1  "  An  Essay,"  &c.,  p.  15,  41,  96,  97,  55,  57,  69.— Jacob  Vanderlint,  as  early  as  17S4, 
declared  that  the  secret  of  the  out-cry  of  the  capitalists  as  to  the  laziness  of  the 
v/orking  people  was  simjDly  that  they  claimed  for  the  same  wages  6  days'  labour 
instead  of  4. 

2  1.  c.  p.  242. 

3  1.  c.  "  The  French,"  he  says,  *'  laugh  at  our  enthusiastic  ideas  of  liberty."  1.  c.p.  78. 

4  *'  They  especially  objected  to  work  beyond  the  12  hours  per  day,  because  the  law 
which  fixed  those  hours,  is  the  only  good  which  remains  to  them  of  the  legislation  of 
the  Eepublic."  ("Kep.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  October,  1856,  p.  80.)  The  French 
Twelve  hours'  Bill  of  September  5th,  1850,  a  bourgeois  edition  of  the  decree  of  the 


The   Working  Day.  26;^ 

of  children  over  10,  is  limited  to  12  hours  ;  in  Aargau  in  186'2, 
the  work  of  children  between  13  and  16,  was  reduced  from 
12J  to  12  hours;  in  Austria  in  1860,  for  children  between  14 
and  16,  the  same  reduction  was  made.^  "  What  a  progress,"  since 
1770  !  Macaulay  would  shout  with  exultation  ! 

The  "  House  of  Terror  "  for  paupers  of  which  the  capitalistic 
soul  of  1770  only  dreamed,  was  realized  a  few  years  later  in  the 
shape  of  a  gigantic  "  Workhouse  "  for  the  industrial  worker 
himself.  It  is  called  the  Factory.  And  the  ideal  this  time 
fades  before  the  reality. 


SECTION  6. — THE   STRUGGLE  FOR  THE  NORMAL  WORKING  DAY.      COMPULSORY 
LIMITATION   BY   LAW    OF   THE    WORKING  TIME.       THE   ENGLISH   FACTORY 

ACTS,  1833  TO  1864. 

After  capital  had  taken  centuries  in  extending  the  working- 
day  to  its  normal  maximum  limit,  and  then  beyond  this  to  the 
limit  of  the  natural  day  of  12  hours,  ^  there  followed  on  the 
birth  of  machinism  and  modern  industry  in  the  last  third  of 

Provisional  Government  of  March  2nd,  1848,  holds  in  all  workshops  without  exceptions. 
Before  this  law  the  working  day  in  France  was  without  definite  limit.  It  lasted  in 
the  factories  14,  15,  or  more  hours.  See  "  Des  classes  ouvrieres  en  France,  pendant 
I'annee  1848.  Par  M.  Blanqui."  M.  Blanqui  the  economist,  not  the  Eevolutionist,  had 
been  entrusted  by  the  Government  with  an  inquiry  into  the  condition  of  the  work- 
ing class. 

1  Belgium  is  the  model  bourgeois  state  in  regard  to  the  regulation  of  the  working 
day.  Lord  Howard  of  Welden,  English  Plenipotentiary  at  Brussels,  reports  to  the 
Foreign  Office,  May  12th,  18ti2 :  "M.  Rogier,  the  minister,  informed  me  that 
children's  labour  is  limited  neither  by  a  general  law  nor  by  any  local  regulations ; 
that  the  Government,  during  the  last  three  years,  intended  in  every  session  to  pro- 
pose a  bill  on  the  subject,  but  always  found  an  insuperable  obstacle  in  the  jealous 
opposition  to  any  legislation  in  contradiction  with  the  principle  of  perfect  freedom  of 
labour." 

2  "  It  is  certainly  much  to  be  regretted  that  any  class  of  persons  should  toil  12  hours 
a  day,  which,  including  the  time  for  their  meals  and  for  going  to  and  returning  from 
their  work,  amounts,  in  fact,  to  14  of  the  24  hours  ....  Without  entering  into  the 
question  of  health,  no  one  one  will  hesitate,  I  think,  to  admit  that,  in  a  moral  point 
of  view,  so  entire  an  absorption  of  the  time  of  the  working  classes,  without  intermission, 
from  the  early  age  of  13,  and  in  trades  not  subject  to  restriction,  much  younger,  must 
be  extremely  prejudicial,  and  is  an  evil  greatly  to  be  deplored  ....  For  the  sake, 
therefore,  of  public  morals,  of  bringing  up  an  orderly  population,  and  of  giving  the 
great  body  of  the  people  a  leasonable  enjoyment  of  life,  it  is  much  to  be  desired  that 
in  all  trades  some  portion  of  every  working  day  should  be  reserved  for  rest  and  leisure." 
(Leonard  Horner  in  Reports  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,  Dec,  1841.) 


264  Capitalist  Prodtidion, 

the  18th  century,  a  violent  encroachment  like  that  of  an 
avalanche  in  its  intensity  and  extent.  All  bounds  of  morals 
and  nature,  age  and  sex,  day  and  night,  were  broken  down. 
Even  the  ideas  of  day  and  night,  of  rustic  simplicity  in  the  old 
statutes,  became  so  confused  that  an  English  judge,  as  late  as 
1860,  needed  a  quite  Talmudic  sagacity  to  explain  "judicially" 
what  was  day  and  what  was  night/  Capital  celebrated  its 
orgies. 

As  soon  as  the  working  class,  stunned  at  first  by  the  noise 
and  turmoil  of  the  new  S37stem  of  production,  recovered,  in 
some  measure,  its  senses,  its  resistance  began,  and  first  in  the 
native  land  of  machinism,  in  England.  For  30  years,  however, 
the  concessions  conquered  by  the  v/orkpeople  were  purely 
nominal.  Parliment  passed  5  Labour  Laws  between  1802  and 
1883,  but  was  shrewd  enough  not  to  vote  a  penny  for  their 
carrjdng  out,  for  the  requisite  officials,  &c.'' 

They  remained  a  dead  letter.  "  The  fact  is,  that  prior  to  the 
Act  of  1833,  young  persons  and  children  were  worked  all  night, 
all  day,  or  both  ad  libitum^  ^ 

A  normal  working  day  for  modern  industry  only  dates  from 
the  Factory  Act  of  1833,  which  included  cotton,  wool,  flax,  and 
silk  factories.  Nothing  is  more  characteristic  of  the  spirit  of 
capital  than  the  history  of  the  English  Factory  Acts  from  1833 
to  1864. 

The  Act  of  1833  declares  the  ordinary  factory  working  day  to 
be  from  half-past  five  in  the  morning  to  half-past  eight  in  the 
evening,  and  within  these  limits,  a  period  of  15  hours,  it  is  law- 
ful to  employ  young  persons  (i.e.,  persons  between  13  and  18  years 

1  See  "Judgment  of  Mr.  J.  H.  Otwey,  Belfast.  Hilary  Sessions,  County  Antrim, 
1860." 

2  It  is  very  characteristic  of  the  regime  of  Louis  Philippe,  the  bourgeois  king,  that 
the  one  Factory  Act  passed  during  his  reign,  that  of  March  22nd,  1841,  was  never 
put  in  force.  And  this  law  only  dealt  with  child-labour.  It  fixed  8  hours  a  day  for 
children  betwf  en  8  and  12,  12  hours  for  children  between  12  and  16,  &c.,  with  many 
exceptions  which  allow  night-work  even  for  children  8  years  old.  The  supervision 
and  enforcement  of  this  law  are,  in  a  country  where  every  mouse  is  under  police 
administration,  left  to  the  good-will  of  the  amis  du  commerce.  Only  since  1853, 
in  one  single  department — the  Departement  du  Nord — has  a  paid  government  inspector 
been  appointed.  Not  less  characteristic  of  the  development  of  French  society, 
generally,  is  the  fact,  that  Louis  Philippe's  law  stood  solitary  among  the  all-embracing 
mass  of  French  laws,  till  the  Revolution  of  1848. 

3  "  Report  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  30th  April,  1860,  p.  50. 


The  Working  Day.  265 

of  age),  at  any  time  of  the  day,  provided  no  one  individual 
young  person  should  work  more  than  12  hours  in  any  one  day, 
except  in  certain  cases  especially  provided  for.  The  6th  section 
of  the  Act  provided :  "  That  there  shall  be  allowed  in  the  course 
of  every  day  not  less  than  one  and  a  half  hours  for  meals  to 
every  such  person  restricted  as  hereinbefore  provided."  The 
employment  of  children  under  9,  with  exceptions  mentioned 
later,  was  forbidden;  the  work  of  children  between  9  and  13 
was  limited  to  8  hours  a  day,  nis^ht  work,  i.e.,  according  to  this 
Act,  work  between  8.30  p.m.  and  5.30  a.m.,  was  forbidden  for 
all  persons  between  9  and  18. 

The  law-makers  were  so  far  from  wishing  to  trench  on  the 
freedom  of  capital  to  exploit  adult  labour-power,  or,  as  they 
called" it,  "the  freedom  of  labour,"  that  they  created  a  special 
system  in  order  to  prevent  the  Factory  Acts  from  having  a 
consequence  so  outrageous. 

"  The  great  evil  of  the  factory  system  as  at  present  con- 
ducted," says  the  first  report  of  the  Central  Board  of  the  Com- 
mission of  June  28th,  1833,  "  has  appeared  to  us  to  be  that  it 
entails  the  necessity  of  continuing  the  labour  of  children  to 
the  utmost  length  of  that  of  the  adults.  The  only  remedy  for 
this  evil,  short  of  the  limitation  of  the  labour  of  adults,  which 
would,  in  our  opinion,  create  an  evil  greater  than  that  which  is 
sought  to  be  remedied,  appears  to  be  the  plan  of  working 
double  sets  of  children."  .  .  .  Under  the  name  of  System 
of  Relays,  this  "  plan  "  was  therefore  carried  out,  so  that,  e.g., 
from  5.30  a.m.  until  1.30  in  the  afternoon,  one  set  of  children 
between  9  and  13,  and  from  1.30  p.m.  to  8.30  in  the  evening 
another  set  were  "  put  to,"  &c. 

In  order  to  reward  the  manufacturers  for  having,  in  the 
most  barefaced  way,  ignored  all  the  Acts  as  to  children's  labour 
passed  during  the  last  twenty-two  years,  the  pill  was  yet 
further  gilded  for  them.  Parliament  decreed  that  after  March 
1st,  1834,  no  child  under  11,  after  March  1st,  1835,  no  child 
under  12,  and  after  March  1st,  1836,  no  child  under  13,  was  to 
work  more  than  eight  hours  in  a  factory.  This  "liberalism," 
so  full  of  consideration  for  "  capital,"  was  the  more  noteworthy 
as,  Dr.  Farre,  Sir  A.  Carlisle,  Sir  B.  Brodie,  Sir  C.  Bell,  Mr. 


266  Capitalist  Production, 

Guthrie,  &c.,  in  a  word,  the  most  distinguished  physicians  and 
surgeons  in  London,  had  declared  in  their  evidence  before  the 
House  of  Commons,  that  there  was  danger  in  delay.  Dr. 
Farre  expressed  himself  still  more  coarsely.  "  Legislation  is 
necessary  for  the  prevention  of  death,  in  any  form  in  which  it 
can  be  prematurely  inflicted,  and  certainly  this  {i.e.y  the  factory 
method)  must  be  viewed  as  a  most  cruel  mode  of  inflicting  it." 

That  same  *'  reformed  "  Parliament,  which  in  its  delicate  con- 
sideration for  the  manufacturers,  condemned  children  under  13, 
for  years  to  come,  to  72  hours  of  work  per  week  in  the  Factory 
Hell,  on  the  other  hand,  in  the  Emancipation  Act,  which  also 
administered  freedom  drop  by  drop,  forbade  the  planters,  from 
the  outset,  to  work  any  negro  slave  more  than  45  hours  a 
week. 

But  in  no  wise  conciliated,  capital  now  began  a  noisy  agitation 
that  went  on  for  several  years.  It  turned  chiefly  on  the  age  of 
those  who,  under  the  name  of  children,  were  limited  to  8  hours 
work,  and  were  subject  to  a  certain  amount  of  compulsory 
education.  According  to  capitalistic  anthropology,  the  age  of 
childhood  ended  at  10,  or  at  the  outside,  at  11.  The  more 
nearly  the  time  approached  for  the  coming  into  full  force  of 
the  Factory  Act,  the  fatal  year  1836,  the  more  wildly  raged 
the  mob  of  manufacturers.  They  managed,  in  fact,  to  intimidate 
the  government  to  such  an  extent  that  in  1885  it  proposed  to 
lower  the  limit  of  the  age  of  childhood  from  13  to  12.  In  the 
meantime  the  pressure  from  without  grew  more  threatening. 
Courage  failed  the  House  of  Commons.  It  refused  to  throw 
children  of  13  under  the  Juggernaut  Car  of  capital  for  more 
than  8  hours  a  day,  and  the  Act  of  1833  came  into  full  operation. 
It  remained  unaltered  until  June,  1844. 

In  the  ten  years  during  which  it  regulated  factory  work, 
first  in  part,  and  then  entirel}'-,  the  official  reports  of  the  factory 
inspectors  teem  with  complaints  as  to  the  impossibility  of 
putting  the  Act  into  force.  As  the  law  of  1833  left  it  optional 
with  the  lords  of  capital  during  the  15  hours,  from  5.30  a.m.  to 
8.30  p.m.,  to  make  every  "  young  person,"  and  "  every  child  " 
begin,  break  off,  resume,  or  end  his  12  or  8  hours  at  any 
moment   they  liked,  and  also  permitted  them  to   assign   to 


The   Working  Day.  267 

different  persons,  different  times  for  meals,  these  gentlemen 
soon  discovered  a  new  "  system  of  relays,"  by  which  the  labour- 
horses  were  not  changed  at  fixed  stations,  but  were  constantly 
re-harnessed  at  changing  stations.  We  do  not  pause  longer  on 
the  beauty  of  this  system,  as  we  shall  have  to  return  to  it  later. 
But  this  much  is  clear  at  the  first  glance  :  that  this  system 
annulled  the  whole  Factory  Act,  not  only  in  the  spirit,  but  in 
the  letter.  How  could  factory  inspectors,  with  this  complex 
book-keeping  in  respect  to  each  individual  child  or  young 
person,  enforce  the  legally  determined  work  time  and  the 
granting  of  the  legal  meal- times  ?  In  a  great  many  of  the 
factories,  the  old  brutalities  soon  blossomed  out  again  un- 
punished. In  an  interview  with  the  Home  Secretary  (1844), 
the  factory  inspectors  demonstrated  the  impossibility  of  any 
control  under  the  newly  invented  relay  system.^  In  the  mean- 
time, however,  circumstances  had  greatly  changed.  The  factory 
hands,  especially  since  1838,  had  made  the  Ten  Hours'  Bill  their 
economical,  as  they  had  made  the  Charter  their  political, 
election-cry.  Some  of  the  manufacturers,  even,  who  had 
managed  their  factories  in  conformity  with  the  Act  of  1833, 
overwhelmed  Parliament  with  memorials  on  the  immoral  com- 
petition of  their  false  brethren  whom  greater  impudence,  or 
more  fortunate  local  circumstances,  enabled  to  break  the  law. 
Moreover,  however  much  the  individual  manufacturer  might 
give  the  rein  to  liis  old  lust  for  gain,  the  spokesmen  and 
political  leaders  of  the  manufacturing  class  ordered  a  change 
of  front  and  of  speech  towards  the  workpeople.  The}^  had 
entered  upon  the  contest  for  the  repeal  of  the  Corn  Laws,  and 
needed  the  workers  to  help  them  to  victory.  They  promised, 
therefore,  not  only  a  double-sized  loaf  of  bread,  but  the  enact- 
ment of  the  Ten  Hours'  Bill  in  the  Free  Trade  millenium.^  Thus 
they  still  less  dared  to  oppose  a  measure  intended  onty  to  make 
the  law  of  1833  a  reality.  Threatened  in  their  holiest  interest, 
the  rent  of  land,  the  Tories  thundered  with  philanthropic  in- 
dignation against  the  "  nefarious  practices  "  *  of  their  foes. 

1  •'  Rept.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  October,  1849,  p.  6. 

2  "  Rept.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  October,  1848,  p.  98. 

3  Leonard  Horner  \ises  the  expression  "nefarious  practices"  in  his  official  reports. 
("  Report  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  October,  1850,  p.  7.) 


2 68  Capitalist  Production, 

This  was  the  origin  of  the  additional  Factory  Act  of  June 
7th,  1844.  It  came  into  effect  oii  September  10th,  1844.  It 
places  under  protection  a  new  category  of  workers,  viz.,  the 
.women  over  18.  They  were  placed  in  every  respect  on  the 
same  footing  as  the  young  persons,  their  work  time  limited  to 
twelve  hours,  their  night-labour  forbidden,  &;c.  For  the  first 
time,  legislation  saw  itself  compelled  to  control  directly  and 
officially  the  labour  of  adults.  In  the  Factory  Report  of  1844- 
1845,  it  is  said  with  irony  :  "  No  instances  have  come  to  my 
knowledge  of  adult  women  having  expressed  any  regret  at 
their  rights  being  thus  far  interfered  with."  ^  The  working  time 
of  children  under  13  was  reduced  to  6  J,  and  in  certain  circum^ 
stances  to  7  hours  a-day.^ 

To  get  rid  of  the  abuses  of  the  "  spurious  relay-system,"  the 
law  established  besides  others  the  following  important  regula- 
tions : — "  That  the  hours  of  work  of  children  and  young  persons 
shall  be  reckoned  from  the  time  when  any  child  or  young 
person  shall  begin  to  work  in  the  morning."  So  that  if  A, 
e.g.y  begins  work  at  8  in  the  morning,  and  B  at  10,  B's  work- 
day must  nevertheless  end  at  the  same  hour  as  A's.  "  The 
time  shall  be  regulated  by  a  public  clock,"  for  example,  the 
nearest  railway  clock,  by  which  the  factory  clock  is  to  be  set. 
The  occupier  is  to  hang  up  a  "  legible  "  printed  notice  stating 
the  hours  for  the  beginning  and  ending  of  work  and  the  times 
allowed  for  the  several  meals.  Children  beginning  work  before 
12  noon  may  not  be  again  employed  after  1  p.m.  The  after- 
noon shift  must  therefore  consist  of  other  children  than  those 
employed  in  the  morning.  Of  the  hour  and  a  half  for  meal 
times,  "  one  hour  thereof  at  the  least  shall  be  given  before 
three  of  the  clock  in  the  afternoon.  .  .  .  and  at  the  same 
period  of  the  day.  No  child  or  young  person  shall  be  employed 
more  than  five  hours  before  1  p.m.  without  an  interval  for  meal 
time  of  at  least  80  minutes.  No  child  or  young  person  [or 
female]  shall  be  employed  or  allowed  to  remain  in  any  room  in 
which  any  manufacturing  process  is  then  [^.e.,  at  meal  times] 
carried  on,"  &c. 

1  "  Kept.,"  &c.,  30th  Sept.,  1844,  p.  15. 

2  The  Act  allows  children  to  be  employed  for  10  hours  if  they  do  not  work  day  after 
day,  but  only  on  alternate  days.     In  the  main,  this  clause  remained  inoperative. 


The  Working  Day.  269 

It  has  been  seen  that  these  minutiae,  which,  with  military 
uniformity,  regulate  by  stroke  of  the  clock  the  times,  limits, 
pauses  of  the  work,  were  not  at  all  the  products  of  Parlia- 
mentary fancy.  They  developed  gradually  out  of  circum- 
stances as  natural  laws  of  the  modern  mode  of  production. 
Their  formulation,  official  recognition,  and  proclamation  by  the 
State,  were  the  result  of  a  long  struggle  of  classes.  One  of 
tlieir  first  consequences  was  that  in  practice  the  working  day 
of  the  adult  males  in  factories  became  subject  to  the  same 
limitations,  since  in  most  processes  of  production  the  co-opera- 
tion of  the  children,  young  persons,  and  women  is  indispens- 
able. On  the  whole,  therefore,  during  the  period  from  1844 
to  1847,  the  12  hours'  working  day  became  general  and 
uniform  in  all  branches  of  industry  under  the  Factory  Act. 

The  manufacturers,  however,  did  not  allow  this  "  progress  " 
without  a  compensating  "  retrogression."  At  their  instigation 
the  House  of  Commons  reduced  the  minimum  age  for  exploit- 
able children  from  9  to  8,  in  order  to  assure  that  additional 
supply  of  factory  children  which  is  due  to  capitalists,  accord- 
ing to  divine  and  human  iaw.^ 

The  years  1846-47  are  epoch-making  in  the  economic  history 
of  England.  The  Repeal  of  the  Corn  Laws,  and  of  the  duties 
on  cotton  and  other  raw  material ;  free  trade  proclaimed  as  the 
guiding  star  of  legislation  ;  in  a  word,  the  arrival  of  the  mil- 
lenium.  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  same  years,  the  Chartist 
movement  and  the  10  hours'  agitation  reached  their  highest 
point.  They  found  allies  in  the  Tories  panting  for  revenge. 
Despite  the  fanatical  opposition  of  the  army  of  perjured  Free- 
traders, with  Bright  and  Cobden  at  their  head,  the  Ten  Hours' 
Bill,  struggled  for  so  long,  went  through  Parliament. 

The  new  Factory  Act  of  June  8th,  1847,  enacted  that  on 
July  1st,  1847,  there  should  be  a  preliminary  shortening  of  the 
working  day  for  "young  persons"  (from  18  to  18),  and  all 
females  to  11  hours,  but  that  on  May  1st,  1848,  there  should 
be  a  definite  limitation  of  the  working  day  to  10  hours.     In 

1  '*  As  a  reduction  in  their  hours  of  work  would  cause  a  larger  number  (of  children) 
to  be  employed,  it  was  thouglit  that  the  additional  supply  of  children  from  8  to  9 
years  of  age  would  meet  the  increased  demand  "  (I.e.,  p.  13). 


270  Capitalist  P^^odudion. 

other  respects,  the  Act  only  amended  and  completed  the  Acts 
of  1833  and  1844. 

Capital  now  entered  upon  a  preliminary  campaign  in  order 
to  hinder  the  Act  from  coming  into  full  force  on  May  1st,  1 848. 
And  the  workers  themselves,  under  the  pretence  that  they  had 
been  taught  by  experience,  were  to  help  in  the  destruction  of 
their  own  work.  The  moment  was  cleverly  chosen.  "  It  must 
be  remembered,  too,  that  there  has  been  more  than  two  years 
of  great  suffering  (in  consequence  of  the  terrible  crisis  of  1846- 
47)  among  the  factory  operatives,  from  many  mills  having 
worked  short  time,  and  many  being  altogether  closed.  A  con- 
siderable number  of  the  operatives  must  therefore  be  in  very 
narrow  circumstances ;  many,  it  is  to  be  feared,  in  debt ;  so 
that  it  might  fairly  have  been  pi'esumed  that  at  the  present 
time  they  would  prefer  working  the  longer  time,  in  order  to 
make  up  for  past  losses,  perhaps  to  pay  off  debts,  or  get  their 
furniture  out  of  pawn,  or  replace  that  sold,  or  to  get  a  n^^ 
supply  of  clothes  for  themselves  and  their  families."^ 

The  manufacturers  tried  to  aggravate  the  natural  effect  of 
these  circumstances  by  a  general  reduction  of  wages  by  10%. 
This  was  done,  so  to  say,  to  celebrate  the  inauguration  of  the 
new  Free  Trade  era.  Then  followed  a  further  reduction  of  8J% 
as  soon  as  the  working  day  was  shortened  to  11,  and  a  reduc- 
tion of  double  that  amount  as  soon  as  it  was  finally  shortened 
to  10  hours.  Wherever,  therefore,  circumstances  allowed  it,  a 
reduction  of  wages  of  at  least  257o  took  place.^  Under  such 
favourably  prepared  conditions  the  agitation  among  the  factory 
workers  for  the  repeal  of  the  Act  of  1847  was  begun.  Neither 
lies,  bribery,  nor  threats  were  spared  in  this  attempt.  But  all 
was  in  vain.  Concerning  the  half-dozen  petitions  in  which 
workpeople  were  made  to  complain  of  "  their  oppression  by 
the  Act,"  the  petitioners  themselves  declared  under  oral  ex- 
amination, that  their  signatures  had  been  extorted  from  them, 
"  They   felt   themselves   oppressed,   but  not   exactly   by   the 

1  "  Eep.  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,"  31st  Oct.,  1848,  p.  16. 

2  *'  I  found  that  men  who  had  been  getting  10s.  a  week,  had  had  Is.  taken  off  for 
a  reduction  in  the  rate  of  10  per  cent,  and  Is.  6d.  off  the  remaining  9s.  for  the  reduc- 
tion in  time,  together  2s.  6d.,  and  notwithstanding  this,  many  of  them  said  they 
would  rather  work  10  hours."  1.  c. 


The   Working  Day,  271 

Factory  Act."  ^  But  if  the  manufacturers  did  not  succeed  in 
making  the  workpeople  speak  as  they  wished,  they  them- 
selves shrieked  all  the  louder  in  press  and  Parliament  in  the 
name  of  the  workpeople.  They  denounced  the  Factory 
Inspectors  as  a  kind  of  revolutionary  commissioners  like  those 
of  the  French  National  Convention  ruthlessly  sacrificing  the 
unhappy  factory  workers  to  their  humanitarian  crotchet.  This 
manoeuvre  also  failed.  Factory  Inspector  Leonard  Horner 
conducted  in  his  own  person,  and  through  his  sub-inspectors, 
many  examinations  of  witnesses  in  the  factories  of  Lancashire. 
About  707o  of  the  workpeople  examined  declared  in  favour 
of  10  hours,  a  much  smaller  percentage  in  favour  of  11,  and  an 
altogether  insignificant  minority  for  the  old  12  hours.^ 

Another  "friendly"  dodge  was  to  make  the  adult  males 
work  12  to  15  hours,  and  then  to  blazon  abroad  this  fact  as 
the  bdst  proof  of  what  the  proletariat  desired  in  its  heart  of 
hearts.  But  the  "ruthless"  Factory  Inspector  Leonard  Horner 
was  again  to  the  fore.  The  majority  of  the  "over- timers" 
declared :  "  They  would  much  prefer  working  ten  hours  for 
less  wages,  but  that  they  had  no  choice ;  tliat  so  many  were 
out  of  employment  (so  many  spinners  getting  very  low  wages 
by  having  to  work  as  piecers,  being  unable  to  do  better),  that 
if  they  refused  to  work  the  longer  time,  others  would  immedi- 
ately get  their  places,  so  that  it  was  a  question  with  them  of 
agreeing  to  work  the  long  time,  or  of  being  thrown  out  of 
employment  altogether."  ^ 

The  preliminary  campaign  of  capital  thus  came  to  grief,  and 
the  Ten  Hours'  Act  came  into  force  May  1st,  1848.  But  mean- 
while the  fiasco   of  the   Chartist  party  whose  leaders  were 

1  * '  Though  I  signed  it  [the  petition],  I  said  at  the  time  I  was  putting  my  hand  to  a 
wrong  thing.'  ' Then  why  did  you  put  your  hand  to  it? '  'Because  I  should  have 
been  turned  off  if  I  had  refused.'  Whence  it  would  appear  that  this  petitioner  felt 
himself  '  oppressed,'  but  not  exactly  by  the  Factory  Act."  1.  c.  p.  102. 

2  p.  17,  1.  c.  In  Mr.  Horner's  district  10,270  adult  male  labourers  were  thus 
examined  in  101  factories.  Their  evidence  is  to  be  found  in  the  appendix  to  the 
Factory  Keports  for  the  half-year  ending  October  1848.  These  examinations  furnish 
valuable  material  in  other  connexions  also. 

3  1.  c.  See  the  evidence  collected  by  Leonard  Horner  himself,  Nos.  69,  70,  71,  72, 
92,  93,  and  that  collected  by  Sub-Inspector  A.,  Nos.  51,  52,  58,  59,  62,  70,  of  the 
Appendix.  One  manufacturer,  too,  tells  the  plain  truth.  See  No.  14,  and  No. 
265, 1.  c. 


2/2  Capitalist  Production. 

imprisoned,  and  whose  organisation  was  dismembered,  had 
shaken  the  confidence  of  the  English  working  class  in  its  own 
strength.  Soon  after  this  the  June  insurrections  in  Paris  and 
its  bloody  suppression  united,  in  England  as  on  the  Continent, 
all  fractions  of  the  ruling  classes,  landlords  and  capitalists, 
stock-exchange  wolves  and  shop-keepers.  Protectionists  and 
Free-traders,  government  and  opposition,  priests  and  free- 
thinkers, young  whores  and  old  nuns,  under  the  common  cry 
for  the  salvation  of  Property,  Religion,  the  Family  and 
Society.  The  working  class  was  everywhere  proclaimed, 
placed  under  a  ban,  under  a  virtual  law  of  suspects.  The 
manufacturers  had  no  need  any  longer  to  restrain  themselves. 
They  broke  out  in  open  revolt  not  only  against  the  Ten  Hours' 
Act,  but  against  the  whole  of  the  legislation  that  since  1833 
had  aimed  at  restricting  in  some  measure  the  "  free  "  exploita- 
tion of  labour-power.  It  was  a  pro-slavery  rebellion  in  minia- 
ture, carried  on  for  over  two  years  with  a  cynical  recklessness, 
a  terrorist  energy  all  the  cheaper  because  the  rebel  capitalist 
risked  nothing  except  the  skin  of  his  "  hands." 

To  understand  that  which  follows  we  must  remember  that 
the  Factory  Acts  of  1833,  1844<,  and  1847  were  all  three  in 
force  so  far  as  the  one  did  not  amend  the  other :  that  not  one 
of  these  limited  the  working  day  of  the  male  worker  over  18, 
and  that  since  1833  the  15  hours  from  5.30  a.m.  to  8.30  p.m. 
had  remained  the  legal  "  day,"  within  the  limits  of  which 
at  first  the  12,  and  later  the  10  hours'  labour  of  young 
persons  and  women  had  to  be  performed  under  the  prescribed 
conditions. 

The  manufacturers  began  by  here  and  there  discharging  a 
part  of,  in  many  cases  half  of,  the  young  persons  and  women 
employed  by  them,  and  then,  for  the  adult  males,  restoring 
the  almost  obsolete  night-work.  The  Ten  Hours'  Act,  they 
cried,  leaves  no  other  alternative.^ 

Their  second  step  dealt  with  the  legal  pauses  for  meals. 
Let  us  hear  the  Factory  Inspectors.  "  Since  the  restriction  of 
the  hours  of  work  to  ten,  the  factory  occupiers  maintain, 
although  they  have  not  yet  practically  gone  the  whole  length, 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1848,  p.  133,  134. 


The   Working  Day,  273 

that  supposing  the  hours  of  work  to  be  from  9  a.m.  to  7  p.m., 
they  fulfil  the  provisions  of  the  statutes  by  allowing  an  hour 
before  9  a.m.  and  half-an-hour  after  7  p.m.  [for  meals].  In 
some  cases  they  now  allow  an  hour,  or  half  an  hour  for  dinner, 
insisting  at  the  same  time,  that  they  are  not  bound  to  allow 
any  part  of  the  hour  and  a  half  in  the  course  of  the  factory 
working-day."^  The  manufacturers  maintained  therefore  that 
the  scrupulously  strict  provisions  of  the  Acts  of  1844  with 
regard  to  meal  times  only  gave  the  operatives  permission  to  eat 
and  drink  before  coming  into,  and  after  leaving  the  factory — 
Z.6.,  at  home.  And  why  should  not  the  workpeople  eat  their 
dinner  before  9  in  the  morning?  The  crown  lawyers,  how- 
ever, decided  that  the  prescribed  meal  times  "  must  be  in  the 
interval  during  the  working  hours,  and  that  it  will  not  be 
lawful  to  work  for  10  hours  continuously,  from  9  a.m.  to  7 
p.m.,  without  any  interval."^ 

After  these  pleasant  demonstrations.  Capital  preluded  its 
revolt  by  a  step  which  agreed  with  the  letter  of  the  law  of 
1844,  and  was  therefore  legal. 

The  Act  of  1844  certainly  prohibited  the  employment  after 

1  p.m.  of  such  children,  from  8  to  13,  as  had  been  employed 
before  noon.  But  it  did  not  regulate  in  any  way  the  6J 
hours' work  of  the  children  whose  work- time  began  at  12  mid- 
day or  later.  Children  of  8  might,  if  they  began  work  at  noon, 
be  employed  from  12  to  1,  1  hour  ;  from  2  to  4  in  the  afternoon, 

2  hours ;  from  5  to  8.80  in  the  evening,  8 J  hours ;  in  all,  the 
legal  6-|  hours.  Or  better  still.  In  order  to  make  tlieir  work 
coincide  with  that  of  the  adult  male  labourers  up  to  8.30  p.m., 
the  manufacturers  only  had  to  give  them  no  work  till  2  in  the 
afternoon ;  they  could  then  keep  them  in  the  factory  without 
intermission  till  8.30  in  the  evening.  "  And  it  is  now  expressly 
admitted  that  the  practice  exists  in  England  from  the  desire 
of  mill-owners  to  have  their  machinery  at  work  for  more  than 
10  hours  a-day,  to  keep  the  children  at  work  with  male 
adults  after  all  the  young  persons  and  women  have  left, 
and  until  8.30  p.m.,  if  the  factory -owners  choose."^     Workmen 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1848,  p.  47. 
«  Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1848,  p.  130. 
8  Reports,  &c.,  1.  c,  p.  142. 
3 


274  Capitalist  Pi^oductzon. 

and  factory  inspectors  protested  on  hygienic  and  moral  grounds, 
but  Capital  answered : 

**  My  deeds  upon  my  head  !     I  crave  the  law, 
The  penalty  and  forfeit  of  my  bond." 

In  fact,  according  to  statistics  laid  before  the  House  of  Com- 
mons on  July  26th,  1850,  in  spite  of  all  protests,  on  July  15th, 
1850,  3,742  children  were  subjected  to  this  "  practice  "  in  257 
factories/  Still,  this  was  not  enough.  The  lynx  eye  of 
Capital  discovered  that  the  Act  of  1844  did  not  allow  5  hours' 
work  before  mid-day  without  a  pause  of  at  least  30  minutes  for 
refreshment,  Vjut  prescribed  nothing  of  the  kind  for  work  after 
mid-day.  Therefore,  it  claimed  and  obtained  the  enjoyment 
not  only  of  making  children  of  8  drudge  without  intermission 
from  2  to  8.80  p.m.,  but  also  of  making  them  hunger  during 

that  time. 

'*  Jky,  his  heart, 
So  says  the  bond.'"* 

This  Shylock-clinging  to  the  letter  of  the  law  of  1844,  so  far 
as  it  regulated  children's  labour,  was  but  to  lead  up  to  an  open 
revolt  against  the  same  law,  so  far  as  i't  regulated  the  labour  of 
"  young  persons  and  women."  It  will  be  remembered  that  the 
abolition  of  the  "  false  relay  system  "  was  the  chief  aim  and 
object  of  that  law.  The  masters  began  their  revolt  with  the 
simple  declaration  that  the  sections  of  the  Act  of  1844  which 
prohibited  the  ad  libitum  use  of  young  persons  and  women  in 
such  short  fractions  of  the  day  of  15  hours  as  the  employer 
chose,  were  "  comparatively  harmless  "  so  long  as  the  work- 
time  was  fixed  at  12  hours.  But  under  the  Ten  Hours'  Act 
they  were  a  "  grievous  hardship."^     They  informed  the   in- 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1850,  pp.  5,  6. 

2  The  nature  of  capital  remains  the  same  in  its  develojjed  as  in  its  undeveloped 
form.  lu  the  code  which  the  influence  of  the  slave-owners,  shortly  before  the  out- 
break of  the  American  civil  war,  imposed  on  the  territory  of  New  Mexico,  it  is  said 
that  the  labourer,  in  as  much  as  the  capitalist  has  bought  his  labour -ijower,  "is  his 
(the  capitalist's)  money."  The  same  view  was  current  among  the  Koman  patricians. 
The  money  they  had  advanced  to  the  plebeian  debtor  had  been  transformed  vid  the 
means  of  subsistence  into  the  flesh  and  blood  of  the  debtor.  This  "  flesh  and  blood  ' 
■were,  therefore,  "their  money."  Hence,  the  Shylock-law  of  the  Ten  Tables. 
Linguet's  hypothesis  that  the  patrician  creditors  from  time  to  time  prepared,  beyond 
the  Tiber,  banquets  of  debtors'  flesh,  may  remain  as  undecided  as  that  of  Daumer  on 
the  Christian  Eucharist. 

3  lieports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1848,  p.  28. 


The   Working  Day.  275 

spec  tors  in  the  coolest  manner  that  they  shoukl  place  them- 
selves above  the  letter  of  the  law,  and  re-introduce  the  old 
system  on  their  own  account.^  They  were  acting  in  the  interests 
of  the  i-1-advised  operatives  themselves,  "  in  order  to  be  able  to 
pay  them  higher  wages."  "  This  was  the  only  possible  plan  by 
which  to  maintain,  under  the  Ten  Hours'  Act,  the  industrial 
supremacy  of  Great  Britain."  "  Perhaps  it  may  be  a  little 
dilficult  to  detect  irregularities  under  the  relay  system ;  but 
what  of  that  ?  Is  the  great  manufacturing  interest  of  this 
country  to  be  treated  as  a  secondary  matter  in  order  to  save 
some  little  trouble  to  Inspectors  and  Sub-Inspectors  of 
Factories  ? "' 

All  these  shifts  naturally  were  of  no  avail.  The  Factory 
Inspectors  appealed  to  the  Law  Courts.  But  soon  such  a  cloud 
of  dust  in  the  way  of  petitions  from  the  masters  overwhelmed 
the  Home  Secretary,  Sir  George  Grey,  that  in  a  circular  of 
August  5th,  1848,  he  recommends  the  inspectors  not  "to  lay 
informations  against  mill-owners  for  a  breach  of  the  letter  of 
the  Act,  or  for  employment  of  young  persons  by  relays  in  cases 
in  which  there  is  no  reason  to  believe  that  such  young  persons 
have  been  actually  employed  for  a  longer  period  than  that 
sanctioned  by  law."  Hereupon,  Factory  Inspector  J.  Stuart 
allowed  the  so-called  relay  system  during  the  15  hours  of  the 
factory  day  throughout  Scotland,  where  it  soon  flourished  again 
as  of  old.  The  English  Factory  Inspectors,  on  the  other  hand, 
declared  that  the  Home  Secretary  had  no  power  dictatorially 
to  suspend  the  law,  and  continued  their  legal  proceedings  against 
the  pro-slavery  rebellion. 

But  what  was  the  good  of  summoning  the  capitalists  when  the 
Courts,  in  this  case  the  country  magistrates — Cobbett  s  "  Great 
Unpaid  " — acquitted  them  \  In  these  tribunals,  the  masters 
sat  in  judgment  on  themselves.  An  example.  One  Eskrigge, 
cotton-spinner,  of  the  firm  of  Kershaw,  Leese,  &  Co.,  had  laid 
before  the  Factory  Inspector  of  his  district  the  scheme  of  a 
relay  system  intended  for  his  mill.  Heceiving  a  refusal,  he  at 
fir«t  kept  quiet.  A  few  months  later,  an  individual  named 
Robinson,  also  a  cotton-spinner,  and  if  not  his  Man  Friday,  at 

1  Thus,  amang  others,  Philanthropist  Ashworthto  Leonard  Horner,  in  a  d'SgustLiig 
Quaker  letter.     (Reports,  &c.,  April,  1849,  p.  4.) 
=^  1.  c,  p.  140. 


276  Capitalist  Production. 

all  events  related  to  Eskrigge,  appeared  before  the  borough 
magistrates  of  Stockport  on  a  charge  of  introducing  the  identi- 
cal plan  of  relays  invented  by  Eskrigge.  Four  Justices  sat. 
among  them  three  cotton-spinners,  at  their  head  this  same 
inevitable  Eskrigge.  Eskrigge  acquitted  Eobinson,  and  now 
was  of  opinion  that  what  was  right  for  Robinson  was  fair  for 
Eskrigge.  Supported  by  his  own  legal  decision,  he  introduced 
the  system  at  once  into  his  own  factory.^  Of  course,  the  com- 
position of  this  tribunal  was  in  itself  a  violation  of  the  law.^ 
These  judicial  farces,  exclaims  Inspector  Howell,  "  urgently 
call  for  a  remedy — either  that  the  law  should  be  so  altered  as 
to  be  made  to  conform  to  these  decisions,  or  that  it  should 
be  administered  by  a  less  fallible  tribunal,  whose  decisions 
would  conform  to  the  law.  .  .  .  when  these  cases  are  brought 
forward.     I  long  for  a  stipendiary  magistrate."^ 

The  Crown  lawyers  declared  the  masters'  interpretation  of 
the  Act  of  1848  absurd.  But  the  Saviours  of  Society  would 
not  allow  themselves  to  be  turned  from  their  purpose.  Leonard 
Horner  reports,  "  Having  endeavoured  to  enforce  the  Act  .  .  . 
by  ten  prosecutions  in  seven  magisterial  divisions,  and  having 
been  supported  by  the  magistrates  in  one  case  only.  ...  I  con- 
sidered it  useless  to  prosecute  more  for  this  evasion  of  the  law. 
That  part  of  the  Act  of  1884  which  was  framed  for  securing  uni- 
formity in  the  hours  of  woik,  .  .  .  is  thus  no  longer  in  force  in 
m}^  district  (Lancashire).  Neither  have  the  sub-inspectors  or 
myself  any  means  of  satisfying  ourselves,  when  we  inspect  a 
mill  working  by  shifts,  that  the  younor  persons  and  women 
are  not  working  more  than  10  hours  a-day.  ...  In  a  return  of 
the  80th  April,  ...  of  mill-owners  working  by  shifts,  the 
number  amounts  to  114,  and  has  been  for  some  time  rapidly 
increasing.  In  general,  the  time  of  working  the  mill  is  ex- 
tended to  13J  hours,  from  6  a.m.  to  7 J  p.m.,  ...  in  some 
insta,nces  it  amounts  to  15  hours,  from  5 J  a.m.  to  8 J  p.m."^ 
Already,  in  Decernber,  1848,  Leonard  Horner  had  a  list  of  65 
manufacturers  and  29  overlookers  who  unanimously  declared 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  30bh  April,  1849,  pp.  21,  22.     Cf.  like  examples  ibid.  pp.  4,  5. 

2  By  I.  and  II.  Will.  IV.,  ch.  24,  s.  10,  known  as  Sir  John  Hobhouse's  Factory  Act, 
it  was  forbidden  to  any  owner  of  a  cotton-spinning  or  weaving  mill,  or  the  father,  son, 
or  brother  of  such  owner,  to  act  as  Justice  of  the  Peace  in  any  inquiries  that  con- 
c:!rned  the  Factory  Act. 

» l.c.  ♦  Ileports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1849,  p.  5. 


The   Working  Day.  277 

that  no  system  of  supervision  could,  under  this  relay  system, 
prevent  enormous  overwork.^  Now,  the  same  children  and 
3^oung  persons  were  shifted  from  the  spinning-room  to  the 
weaving-room,  now,  during  15  hours,  from  one  factory  to 
another.^  How  was  it  possible  to  control  a  system  which, 
"  under  the  guise  of  relays,  is  some  one  of  the  many  plans  for 
shuffling  'the  hands'  about  in  endless  variety,  and  shifting 
the  hours  of  work  and  of  rest  for  different  individuals  through- 
out the  day,  so  that  you  may  never  have  one  complete  set  of 
hands  workinof  tofj^ether  in  the  same  room  at  the  same  time."^ 

But  altogether  independently  of  actual  overwork,  this  so- 
called  relay-system  was  an  offspring  of  capitalistic  fantasy 
such  as  Fourier, in  his  humorous  sketches  of  "  Courtes  Seances," 
has  never  surpassed,  except  that  the  "  attractionof  labour  "  was 
changed  into  the  attraction  of  capital.  Look,  for  example,  at 
those  schemes  of  the  masters  which  the  "  respectable  "  press 
praised  as  models  of  "  what  a  reasonable  degree  of  care  and 
method  can  accomplish."  The  personnel  of  the  workpeople 
was  sometimes  divided  into  from  12  to  14  categories,  which 
themselves  constantly  changed  and  rechanged  their  constituent 
parts.  During  the  15  hours  of  the  factory  day,  capital  dragged 
in  the  labourer  now  for  30  minutes,  now  for  an  hour,  and  then 
pushed  him  out  again,  to  drag  him  into  the  factory  and  to 
thrust  him  out  afresh,  hounding  him  hither  and  thither,  in 
scattered  shreds  of  time,  without  ever  losing  hold  of  him  until 
the  full  10  hours'  work  was  done.  As  on  the  stage,  the  same 
persons  had  to  appear  in  turns  in  the  different  scenes  of  the 
different  acts.  But  as  an  actor  during  the  whole  course  of 
the  play  belongs  to  the  stage,  so  the  operatives,  during  15 
hours,  belonged  to  the  factory,  without  reckoning  the  time 
for  going  and  coming.  Thus  the  hours  of  rest  were  turned 
into  hours  of  enforced  idleness,  which  drove  the  youths  to 
the  pot-house,  and  the  girls  to  the  brothel.  At  every  new 
trick  that  the  capitalist,  from  day  to  day,  hit  upon  for  keep- 
ing his  machinery  going  12  or  15  hours  without  increasing 
the  number  of  his  hands,  the  worker  had  to  swallow  his  meals 
now  in  this  fragment  of  time,  now  in  that.     At  the  time  of  the 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1849,  p.  6. 

2  Reports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1849,  p.  21. 
»  Reports,  &c.,  for  1st  October,  1848,  p.  95. 


2/8  Capitalist  Production. 

10  hours' agitation,  the  masters  cried  out  that  the  working  mob 
petitioned  in  the  hope  of  obtaining  12  hours'  wages  for  10 
hours'  work.  Now  they  reversed  the  medal.  They  paid  10 
hours'  wages  for  12  or  15  hours'  lordship  over  labour-power.^ 
This  was  the  gist  of  the  matter,  this  the  masters'  interpretation 
of  the  10  hours'  law  !  These  were  the  same  unctuous  free- 
traders, perspiring  with  the  love  of  humanity,  who  for  full  10 
years,  during  the  Anti-Corn  Law  agitation,  had  preached  to 
the  operatives,  by  a  reckoning  of  pounds,  shillings,  and  pence, 
that  with  free  importation  of  corn,  and  with  the  means  pos- 
sessed by  English  industry,  10  hours'  labour  would  be  quite 
enough  to  enrich  the  capitalists.^  This  revolt  of  capital,  after 
two  years,  was  at  last  crowned  with  victory  by  a  decision  of 
one  of  the  four  highest  Courts  of  Justice  in  England,  the 
Court  of  Exchequer,  which  in  a  case  brought  before  it  on 
February  Sth,  1850,  decided  that  the  manufacturers  were 
certainly  acting  against  the  sense  of  the  Act  of  1844,  but  that 
this  Act  itself  contained  certain  words  that  rendered  it  mean- 
ingless. "By  this  decision,  the  Ten  Hours' Act  was  abolished."' 
A  crowd  of  masters,  who  until  then  had  been  afraid  of  using 
the  relay-system  for  young  persons  and  women,  now  took  it  up 
heart  and  soul."* 

But  on  this  apparently  decisive  victory  of  capital,  followed 
at  once  a  revulsion.  The  workpeople  had  hitherto  offered  a 
passive,  although  inflexible  and  unremitting  resistance.  They 
now  protested  in  Lancashire  and  Yorkshire  in  threatening 
meetings.  The  pretended  Ten  Hours'  Act,  was  thus  simple 
humbug,  parliamentary  cheating,  had  never  existed  I  The 
Factory  Inspectors  urgently  warned  the  Government  that  the 
antagonism  of  classes  had  arrived  at  an  incredible  tension. 
Some  of  the  masters  themselves  murmured  :  "  On  account  of 

1  See  Reports,  &c, ,  for  30th  April,  1849,  p.  6,  and  the  detailed  explanation  of  the 
"  shifting  system,"  by  Factory  Inspectors  Howell  and  Saunders,  in  "Reports,  &c.,  for 
31st  October,  1848.''  See  also  the  petition  to  the  Queen  from  the  clergy  of  A.shton 
and  vicinity,  in  the  spring  of  1849,  against  the  "shift  system." 

2  Of.  for  example,  "  The  Factory  Question  and  the  Ten  Hours'  Bill."  By  R.  H. 
Greg,  1837. 

3  F.  Fngels  :  "The  English  Ten  Hours'  Bill."  (In  the  "  Neue  Rheinische  Zeitung, 
Politisch-cekonomische  Revue."  Edited  by  K.  Marx.  April  number,  1850,  p.  13.) 
The  same  "  high  "  Court  of  Justice  discovered,  during  the  American  Civil  War,  a 
verbal  ambiguity  which  exactly  reversed  the  meaning  of  the  law  against  the  arming 
of  pirate  ships. 

4  Rep.,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1850. 


The   Working  Day,  279 

the  contradictory  decisions  of  the  magistrates,  a  condition  of 
thinors  altocrether  abnormal  and  anarchical  obtains.  One  law 
holds  in  Yorkshire,  another  in  Lancashire;  one  law  in  one  parish 
of  Lancashire,  another  in  its  immediate  neighbourhood.  The 
manufacturer  in  large  towns  could  evade  the  law,  the  manu- 
facturer in  country  districts  could  not  find  the  people  necessary 
for  the  relay-system,  still  less  for  the  shifting  of  hands  from 
one  factory  to  another,"  &c.  And  the  first  birthright  of  capital 
is  equal  exploitation  of  labour-power  by  all  capitalists. 

Under  these  circumstances  a  compromise  between  masters 
and  men  was  effected  that  received  the  seal  of  Parliament  in 
the  additional  Factory  Act  of  August  5th,  1850.  The  working 
day  for  "  young  persons  and  women,"  was  raised  from  10  to 
10 J  hours  for  the  first  five  days  of  the  week,  and  was  shortened 
to  1\  on  the  Saturday.  The  work  was  to  go  on  between  6  a.m. 
and  6  p.m.,^  with  pauses  of  not  less  than  \\  hours  for  meal- 
times, these  meal-times  to  be  allowed  at  one  and  the  same  time 
for  all,  and  conformably  to  the  conditions  of  1844.  By  this  an 
end  was  put  to  the  relay-system  once  for  all.^  For  children's 
labour,  the  Act  of  1844  remained  in  force. 

One  set  of  masters,  this  time  as  before,  secured  to  itself 
special  seigneurial  rights  over  the  children  of  the  proletariat. 
These  were  the  silk  manufacturers.  In  1833  they  had  howled 
out  in  threatening  fashion,  "  if  the  liberty  of  working  children 
of  any  age  for  10  hours  a  day  were  taken  away,  it  would  stop 
their  works."  ^  It  would  be  impossible  for  them  to  buy  a  suffi- 
cient number  of  children  over  13.  They  extorted  the  privilege 
they  desired.  The  pretext  was  shown  on  subsequent  investiga- 
tion to  be  a  deliberate  lie.^  It  did  not,  however,  prevent  them, 
during  10  years,  from  spinning  silk  10  hours  a  day  out  of  the 
blood  of  little  children  who  had  to  be  placed  upon  stools  for 
the  performance  of  their  work.''  The  Act  of  1844  certainly 
"  robbed  "  them  of  the  "  liberty  "  of  employing  children  under 
11  longer  than  6 J  hours  a  day.  But  it  secured  to  them,  on  the 
other  hand,  the  privilege  of  working  children  between  11  and 

1  In  winter,  from  7  a.m.  to  7  p.m.  may  be  substituted. 

2  "The  presentlaw  (of  1850)  was  a  compromise  whereby  the  employed  surrendered 
the  benefit  of  the  Ten  Hours'  Act  for  the  advantage  of  one  uniform  period  for  the 
commencement  and  termination  of  the  labour  of  those  whose  labour  is  restricted." 
(Reports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1852,  p.  14.) 

3  Reports,  &c.,  for  Sept.,  1844,  p.  13.  *  1.  c.  '  1.  c. 


28o 


Capitalist  Production, 


13,  10  hours  a  day,  and  of  annulling  in  their  case  the  education 
made  compulsory  for  all  other  factory  children.  This  time  the 
pretext  was  "the  delicate  texture  of  the  fabric  in  which  they 
were  employed,  requiring  a  lightness  of  touch,  only  to  be 
acquired  by  their  early  introduction  to  these  factories."^  The 
children  were  slaughtered  out-and-out  for  the  sake  of  their 
delicate  fingers,  as  in  Southern  Russia  the  horned  cattle  for  the 
sake  of  their  hide  and  tallow.  At  length,  in  1850,  the  privilege 
granted  in  1844  was  limited  to  the  departments  of  silk-twisting 
and  silk-winding.  But  here,  to  make  amends  to  capital  bereft 
of  its  "freedom,"  the  work  time  for  children  from  11  to  13  was 
raised  from  10  to  10 J  hours.  Pretext :  "  Labour  in  silk  mills 
was  lighter  than  in  mills  for  other  fabrics,  and  less  likely  in 
other  respects  also  to  be  prejudicial  to  health."^  Official 
medical  inquiries  proved  afterwards  that,  on  the  contrary,  "  the 
average  death-rate  is  exceedingly  high  in  the  silk  districts,  and 
amongst  the  female  part  of  the  population  is  higher  even  than 
it  is  in  the  cotton  districts  of  Lancashire."  *    Despite  the  pro- 


11.  c. 

2  Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  Oct.,  1861,  p.  26. 

3  1.  c,  p.  27.  On  the  whole  the  working  population,  subject  to  the  Factory  Act, 
has  greatly  improved  physically.  All  medical  testimony  agrees  on  this  point,  and 
personal  observation  at  different  times  has  convinced  me  of  it.  Nevertheless,  and 
txclusive  of  the  terrible  death-rate  of  children  in  the  first  years  of  their  life,  the 
<-»flBcial  reports  of  Dr.  Greenhow  show  the  unfavourable  health  condition  of  the  manu- 
facturing districts  as  compared  with  "agricultural  districts  of  normal  health."  As 
evidence,  take  the  following  table  from  his  1861  report : — 


Percentage 
of  Adult 

Males  en- 
gaged in 
manufac- 
tures. 

Death-rate 

from 
Pulmonary 

Affections 

per  100,000 

Males. 

Name  of  District. 

Death-rate 

from 

Pulmonary 

Affections 

per  100,000 

Females. 

Percentage 
of  Adult 

Females  en- 
gaged in 
manufac- 
tures. 

Kind  of  Female 
Occupation. 

14-9 

598 

Wigan 

644 

18-0 

Cotton 

42-6 

708 

Blackburn 

734 

34-9 

Do. 

37  3 

547 

Halifax 

564 

20-4 

Worsted 

41-9 

611 

Bradford 

603 

30-0 

Do. 

31-0 

691 

Macclesfield 

804 

26-0 

Silk 

14-9 

588 

Leek 

705 

17-2 

Do. 

30-6 

721 

Stoke-upon-Trent 

665 

19-3 

Earthenware 

30-4 

726 

"Woolstanton 
Eight  healthy  agri- 

727 

13-9 

Do. 

305 

cultural  districts 

340 

The   Working  Day,  281 

tests  of  the  Factory  Inspector,  renewed  every  6  months,  the 
mischief  continues  to  this  hour.^ 

The  Act  of  1850  changed  the  15  hours*  time  from  6  a.m.  to 
8.30  p.m.,  into  the  12  hours  from  6  a.m.  to  6  p.m.  for  "young 
persons  and  women  "  only.  It  did  not,  therefore,  affect  children 
who  could  always  be  employed  for  half  an  hour  before  and  2 J 
hours  after  this  period,  provided  the  whole  of  their  labour  did 
not  exceed  %\  hours.  Whilst  the  bill  was  under  discussion,  the 
Factory  Inspectors  laid  before  Parliament  statistics  of  the  in- 
famous abuses  due  to  this  anomaly.  To  no  purpose.  In  the 
background  lurked  the  intention  of  screwing  up,  during  pros- 
perous years,  the  working  day  of  adult  males  to  15  hours  by 
the  aid  of  the  children.  The  experience  of  the  three  following 
years  showed  that  suchan  attempt  must  come  to  grief  against  the 
resistance  of  the  adult  male  operatives.  The  Act  of  1850  was 
therefore  finally  completed  in  1853  by  forbidding  the  "  employ- 
ment of  children  in  the  morning  before  and  in  the  evening  after 
young  persons  and  women."  Henceforth  with  a  few  exceptions 
the  Factory  Act  of  1850  regulated  the  working  day  of  all 
workers  in  the  branches  of  industry  that  come  under  it.^  Since 
the  passing  of  the  first  Factory  Act  half  a  century  had  elapsed.^ 

Factory  legislation  for  the  first  time  went  beyond  its  original 
sphere  in  the  "  Printworks'  Act  of  1845."  The  displeasure  with 
which  capital  received  this  new  "extravagance  "  speaks  through 
every  line  of  the  Act.     It  limits  the  working  day  for  children 

1  It  is  well-known  with  what  reluctance  the  English  "  free  traders  "  gave  up  the 
protective  duty  on  the  silk  manufacture.  Instead  of  the  protection  against  French 
importation,  the  absence  of  protection  to  English  factory  children  now  serves  their 
turn. 

2  During  1859  and  1860,  the  zenith  years  of  the  English  cotton  industry,  some  manu- 
facturers tried,  by  the  decoy  bait  of  higher  wages  for  over-time,  to  reconcile  the  adult 
male  operatives  to  an  extension  of  the  working  day.  The  hand-mule  spinners  and 
self-actor  minders  put  an  end  to  the  experiment  by  a  petition  to  their  employers  in 
which  they  say,  "Plainly  speaking,  our  lives  are  to  us  a  burthen  ;  and,  while  we  are 
confined  to  the  mills  nearly  two  days  a  week  more  than  the  other  operatives  of  the 
country,  we  feel  like  helots  in  the  land,  and  that  we  are  perpetuating  a  system 

injurious  to    ourselves  and  future  generations This,  therefore,  is  to 

give  you  most  respectful  notice  that  when  we  commence  work  again  after  the 
Christmas  and  New  Year's  holidays,  we  shall  work  60  hours  per  week,  and  no  more, 
or  from  six  to  six,  with  one  hour  and  a  half  out. "  (Keports,  &c. ,  for  30th  April, 
1860,  p.  30.) 

8  On  the  means  that  the  wording  of  this  Act  afforded  for  its  violation  cf.  the  Parlia- 
mentary Return  "  Factory  Regulations  Act  "  (6th  August,  1859),  and  in  it  Leonard 
Horner's  "  Suggestions  for  amending  the  Factory  Acts  to  enable  the  Inspectors  to 
prevent  illegal  working,  now  become  very  prevalent." 


202  Capitalist  Production. 

from  8  to  13,  and  for  women  to  16  hours,  between  6  a.ra.  and 
10  p.m.,  without  any  legal  pause  for  meal  times.  It  allows 
males  over  13  to  be  worked  at  will  day  and  night.^  It  is  a 
Parliamentary  abortion.^ 

However,  the  principle  had  triumphed  with  its  victory  in 
those  great  branches  of  industry  which  form  the  most  character- 
istic creation  of  the  modern  mode  of  production.  Their 
wonderful  development  from  1853  to  1860,  hand-in-band  with 
the  physical  and  moral  regeneration  of  the  factory  workers, 
struck  the  most  purblind.  The  masters  from  whom  the  legal 
limitation  and  regulation  had  been  wrung  step  by  step  after  a 
civil  war  of  half  a  century,  themselves  referred  ostentatiously 
to  the  contrast  with  the  branches  of  exploitation  still  "free."^ 
The  Pharisees  of  "  political  economy  "  now  proclaimed  the  dis- 
cernment of  the  necessity  of  a  legally  fixed  working  day  as  a 
characteristic  new  discovery  of  their  "  science."^  It  will  be 
easily  understood  that  after  the  factory  magnates  had  resigned 
themselves  and  become  reconciled  to  the  inevitable,  the  power  of 
resistance  of  capital  gradually  weakened,  whilst  at  the  same 
time  the  power  of  attack  of  the  working  class  grew  with  the 
number  of  its  allies  in  the  classes  of  society  not  immediately 
interested  in  the  question.  Hence  the  comparatively  rapid 
advance  since  1860. 

The  dye-works  and  bleach- works  all  came  under  the  Factory 
Act  of  1850  in  1860  ; '  lace  and  stocking  manufactures  in  1861. 

1"  Children  of  the  age  of  8  years  and  upwards,  have,  indeed,  been  employed  from 
6  a.m.  to  9  p.m.  during  the  last  half  year  in  my  district."  (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st 
October,  1857,  p.  39.) 

2  "  The  Printworks'  Act  is  admitted  to  be  a  failure,  both  with  reference  to  its  educa- 
tional and  protective  provisions."    (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1862,  p.  52.) 

3  Thus,  e.g.,  E.  Potter  in  a  letter  to  the  "Times  "  of  March  24th,  1863.  The 
"Times  "  reminded  him  of  the  manufacturers'  revolt  against  the  Ten  Hours'  Bill. 

4  Thus,  among  others,  Mr.  W.  Newmarch,  collaborator  and  editor  of  Tooke's  "History 
of  Prices."    Is  it  a  scientific  advance  to  make  cowardly  concessions  to  public  opinion? 

5  The  Act  passed  in  1860,  determined  that,  in  regard  to  dye  and  bleach-works,  the 
working  day  should  be  fixed  on  August  1st,  1861,  provisionally  at  12  hours,  and  defin- 
itely on  August  1st,  1862,  at  10  hours,  i.e.,  at  10^  hours  for  ordinary  days,  and  1\  for 
Saturday,  Now,  when  the  fatal  year,  1862,  came,  the  old  farce  was  repeated.  Be- 
sides, the  manufacturers  petitioned  Parliament  to  allow  the  employment  of  young 
persons  and  women  for  12  hours  during  one  year  longer.  "In  the  existing  condition 
of  the  trade  (the  time  of  the  cotton  famine),  it  was  greatly  to  the  advantage  of  the 
operatives  to  work  12  hours  per  day,  and  make  wages  when  they  could,"  A  bill  to 
this  effect  had  been  brought  in,  "  and  it  was  mainly  due  to  the  action  of  the  operative 
bleachers  in  Scotland  that  the  bill  was  abandoned."    (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October, 


The   Working  Day,  28 


o 


In  consequence  of  the  first  report  of  the  Commission  on  the 
employment  of  children  (18G3),  the  same  fate  was  shared  by 
the  manufacturers  of  all  earthenwares  (not  merely  pottery), 
lucifer-matches,  percussion-caps,  cartridges,  carpets,  fustian- 
cutting,  and  many  processes  included  under  the  name  of 
''finishing."     In  the  year  1863  bleaching  in  the  open  air  ^  and 

1862,  J).  14-15.)  Thus  defeated  by  the  very  work-people,  in  whose  name  it  pretended 
to  speak,  Capital  discovered,  with  the  help  of  lawyer  spectacles,  that  the  Act  of  18G0, 
drawn  up,  like  all  the  Acts  of  Parliament  for  the  "protection  of  labour,"  in  equivocal 
phrases,  gave  them  a  pretext  to  exclude  from  its  working  the  calenderers  and  fin- 
ishers. English  jurisprudence,  ever  the  faithful  servant  of  capital,  sanctioned  in  the 
Court  of  Common  Pleas  this  piece  of  pettifogging.  "The  operatives  have  been 
greatly  disappointed  .  .  .  they  have  complained  of  overwork,  and  it  is  greatly  to  be 
regretted  that  the  clear  intention  of  the  legislature  should  have  failed  by  reason  of  a 
faulty  definition."     (1.  c,  p.  18.) 

1  The  "  open-air  bleachers  "  had  evaded  the  law  of  1860,  by  means  of  the  lie  that  no 
women  worked  at  it  in  the  night.  The  lie  was  exposed  by  the  Factory  Inspectors, 
and  at  the  same  time  Parliament  was,  by  petitions  from  the  operatives,  bereft  of 
its  notions  as  to  the  cool  meadow-fragrance,  in  which  bleaching  in  the  open-air  was 
reported  to  take  place.  In  this  aerial  bleaching,  drying  rooms  were  used  at  tempera- 
tures of  from  00'^  to  100°  Fahrenheit,  in  which  the  work  was  done  for  the  most  part  by 
girls.  *'  Cooling"  is  the  technical  expression  for  their  occasional  escape  from  the  dry- 
ing-rooms into  the  fresh  air.  "Fifteen  girls  in  stoves.  Heat  from  80°  to  90°  for 
linens,  and  100°  and  upwards  for  cambrics.  Twelve  girls  ironing  and  doing-up 
in  a  small  room  about  10  feet  square,  in  the  centre  of  which  is  a  close  stove.  The 
girls  stand  round  the  stove,  which  throws  out  a  terrific  heat,  and  dries  the  cambrics 
rapidly  for  the  ironers.  The  hours  of  work  for  these  hands  are  unlimited.  If  busy, 
they  work  till  0  or  12  at  night  for  successive  nights."  (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October, 
1862,  p.  56.)  A  medical  man  states :  "  No  special  hours  are  allowed  for  cooling,  but 
if  the  temperature  gets  too  high,  or  the  workers'  hands  get  soiled  from  perspiration, 

they  are  allowed  to  go  out  for  a  few  minutes My  experience,  which  is 

considerable,  in  treating  the  diseases  of  stove  workers,  compels  me  to  express  the 
opinion  that  their  sanitary  condition  is  by  no  means  so  high  as  that  of  the  operatives 
in  a  spinning  factory  (and  Capital,  in  its  memorials  to  Parliament,  had  painted  them 
as  floridly  healthy,  after  the  manner  of  Rubens).  The  diseases  most  observable 
amongst  them  are  phthisis,  bronchitis,  irregularity  of  uterine  functions,  hysteria  in 
its  most  aggravated  forms,  and  rheumatism.  All  of  these,  I  believe,  are  either 
directly  or  indirectly  induced  by  the  impure,  overheated  air  of  the  apartments  in 
which  the  hands  are  employed,  and  the  want  of  sufficient  comfortable  clothing  to 
protect  them  from  the  cold,  damp  atmosphere,  in  winter,  when  going  to  their 
homes."  (I.e.  p.  56-57.)  The  Factory  Inspectors  remarl  ed  on  the  supplementary  law 
of  1860,  torn  from  these  open-air  bleachers  :  "The  Act  his  not  only  failed  to  afford 
that  protection  to  the  workers  which  it  appears  to  offer,  but  contains  a  clause  ....  ap- 
parently so  worded  that,  unless  persons  are  detected  working  after  8  o'clock  at  night 
they  appear  to  come  under  no  protective  provisions  at  all,  and  if  they  do  so  work,  the 
mode  of  proof  is  so  doubtful  that  a  conviction  can  scarcely  follow."  (1.  c,  p.  52.) 
"To  all  intents  and  purposes,  therefore,  as  an  Act  for  any  benevolent  or  educational 
purpose,  it  is  a  failure  ;  since  it  can  scarcely  be  called  benevolent  to  permit,  which  is 
tantamount  to  compelling,  women  and  children  to  work  14  hours  a  day  with  or  without 
meals,  as  the  case  may  be,  and  perhaps  for  longer  hours  than  these,  withoiit  limit  as 
to  age,  without  reference  to  sex,  and  without  regard  to  the  social  habits  of  the 
families  of  the  neighbourhood,  in  which  such  works  (bleaching  and  dyeing)  are  situ- 
ated."   (Reports,  &c.,  for  30th  April,  1863,  p.  40.) 


284  Capitalist  Pt'oduction. 

baking  were  placed  under  special  Acts,  by  which,  in  the 
former,  the  labour  of  young  persons  and  women  during  the 
night-time  (from  8  in  the  evening  to  6  in  the  morning),  and  in 
the  latter,  the  employment  of  journeymen  bakers  under  18, 
between  9  in  the  evening  and  5  in  the  morning  were  forbidden. 
We  shall  return  to  the  later  proposals  of  the  same  Commission, 
which  threatened  to  deprive  of  their  "  freedom  "  all  the  impor- 
tant branches  of  English  Industry,  with  the  exception  of  agri- 
culture, mines,  and  the  means  of  transport.^ 

bECTION   7. — THE   STRUGGLE   FOR   THE   NORMAL    WORKING-DAY.       RE-ACTION 
OF   THE   ENGLISH   FACTORY   ACTS   ON   OTHER    COUNTRIES. 

The  reader  will  bear  in  mind  that  the  production  of  surplus- 
value,  or  the  extraction  of  surplus-labour,  is  the  specific  end 
and  aim,  the  sum  and  substance,  of  capitalist  production, 
quite  apart  from  any  changes  in  the  mode  of  production,  whicli 
may  arise  from  the  subordination  of  labour  to  capital.  He  will 
remember  that  as  far  as  we  have  at  present  gone,  only  the  inde- 
pendent labourer,  and  therefore  only  the  labourer  legally  quali- 
fied to  act  for  himself,  enters  as  a  vendor  of  a  commodity  into  a 
contract  with  the  capitalist.  If,  therefore,  in  our  historical 
sketch,  on  the  one  hand,  modern  industry;  on  the  other,  the 
labour  of  those  who  are  physically  and  legally  minors,  play 
important  parts,  the  former  was  to  us  only  a  special  depart- 
ment, and  the  latter  onl}^  a  specially  striking  example  of  labour 
exploitation.  Without,  however,  anticipating  the  subsequent 
development  of  our  inquiry,  from  the  mere  connexion  of  the 
historic  facts  before  us,  it  follows  : 

First.  The  passion  of  capital  for  an  unlimited  and  reckless 
extension  of  the  working  day,  is  first  gratified  in  the  industries 
earliest  revolutionised  by  water-power,  steam,  and  machinery, 
in  those  first  creations  of  the  modern  mode  of  production, 
cotton,  wool,  flax,  and  silk  spinning,  and  weaving.  The  changes 
in  the  material  mode  of  production,  and  the  corresponding 
changes  in  the  social  relations  of  the  producers  ^  gave  rise  first 

1  Note  to  the  2n(i  Ed.  Since  1866,  when  I  wrote  the  above  passages,  a  re-action 
has  again  set  in. 

2  "The  conduct  of  each  of  these  classes  (capitalists  and  workmen)  has  been  the 
result  of  the  relative  situation  in  which  they  have  been  placed."  (Reports,  &c.,  for 
31st  October,  1848,  p.  113.) 


The   Working  Day.  285 

to  an  extravagance  beyond  all  bounds,  and  then  in  opposition 
to  this,  called  forth  a  control  on  the  part  of  Society  which 
legally  limits,  regulates,  and  makes  uniform  the  working  day 
and  its  pauses.  This  control  appears,  therefore,  during  the 
first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  simply  as  exceptional 
legislation.^  As  soon  as  this  primitive  dominion  of  the  new 
mode  of  production  was  conquered,  it  was  found  that,  in  the 
meantime,  not  only  had  many  other  branches  of  production 
been  made  to  adopt  the  same  factory  system,  but  that  manu- 
factures with  more  or  less  obsolete  methods,  such  as  potteries, 
glass-making,  &c.,  that  old-fashioned  handicrafts,  like  baking, 
and,  finally,  even  that  the  so-called  domestic  industries,  such 
as  nail-making,  ^  had  long  since  fallen  as  completely  under 
capitalist  exploitation  as  the  factories  themselves.  Legisla- 
tion was,  therefore,  compelled  to  gradually  get  rid  of  its  ex- 
ceptional character,  or  where,  as  in  England,  it  proceeds  after 
the  manner  of  the  Roman  Casuists,  to  declare  any  house  in 
which  work  was  done  to  be  a  factory.^ 

Second,  The  history  of  the  regulation  of  the  working  day  in 
certain  branches  of  production,  and  the  struggle  still  going  on 
in  others  in  regard  to  this  regulation,  prove  conclusively  that 
the  isolated  labourer,  the  labourer  as  "free"  vendor  of  his 
labour-power,  when  capitalist  production  has  once  attained  a 
certain  stage,  succumbs  without  any  power  of  resistance.  The 
creation  of  a  normal  working  day  is,  therefore,  the  product  of 
a  protracted  civil  war,  more  or  less  dissembled,  between  the 
capitalist  class  and  the  working  class.  As  the  contest  takes 
place  in  the  arena  of  modern  industry,  it  first  breaks  out  in 
the  home   of  that  industry — England.*     The  English  factory 

1  '*  The  employments,  placed  under  restriction,  were  connected  vvith  the  manufac- 
ture of  textile  fabrics  by  the  aid  of  steam  or  water-power.  There  were  two  conditions 
to  which  an  employment  must  be  subject  to  cause  it  to  be  inspected,  viz.,  the  use  of 
steam  or  water-power,  and  the  manujfacture  of  certain  specified  fibres."  (Keports, 
&c.,  for  31st  October,  1864,  p.  8.) 

2  On  the  condition  of  so-called  domestic  industries,  specially  valuable  materials 
are  to  be  found  in  the  latest  reports  of  the  Children's  ICmployment  Commission. 

3  "  The  Acts  of  last  Session  (1864)  ....  embrace  a  diversity  of  occupations, 
the  customs  in  which  differ  greatly,  and  the  use  of  mechanical  power  to  give  motion 
to  machinery  is  no  longer  one  of  the  elements  necessary,  as  formerly,  to  constitute, 
in  legal  phrase,  a  *  Factory.'"    (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  October,  1864,  p.  8.) 

4  Belgium,  the  paradise  of  Continental  Liberalism,  shows  no  trace  of  this  move- 
ment. Even  in  the  coal  and  metal  mines,  labourers  of  both  sexes,  and  all  ages,  are 
consumed,  in  perfect  "freedom,"  at  any  period,  and  through  any  length  of  time. 
Of  every  1000  persons  employed  there,  733  are  men,  88  women,  135  boys,  and  44  girls 


286  Capitalist  Production, 

workers  were  the  champions,  not  only  of  the  English,  but  of 
the  modern  working-class  generally,  as  their  theorists  were 
the  first  to  throw  down  the  gauntlet  to  the  theory  of  capital.^ 
Hence,  the  philosopher  of  the  Factory,  Ure,  denounces  as  an 
ineffable  disgrace  ta  the  English  working-class  that  they  in- 
scribed "the  slavery  of  the  Factory  Acts  "  on  the  banner  which 
they  bore  against  capital,  manfully  striving  for  "perfect  free- 
dom of  labour. "2 

France  limps  slowly  behind  England.  The  February  revolu- 
tion was  necessary  to  bring  into  the  world  the  12  hours'  law,* 
which  is  much  more  deficient  than  its  Enorlish  orio'inal.     For 

o  o 

all  that,  the  French  revolutionary  method  has  its  special 
advantages.  It  once  for  all  commands  the  same  limit  to  the 
working-day  in  all  shops  and  factories  without  distinction, 
whilst  English  legislation  reluctantly  yields  to  the  pressure  of 
circumstances,  now  on  this  point,  now  on  that,  and  is  getting 
lost  in  a  hopelessly  bewildering  tangle  of  contradictory  enact- 
ments.^    On  the  other  hand,  the  French  law  proclaims  as  a 

under  16  ;  in  the  blast-furnaces,  &;c.,  of  every  1000,  688  are  men,  149  women,  98 boys, 
and  85  girls  under  16.  Add  to  this  the  low  wages  for  the  enormous  exploitation  of 
mature  and  immature  labour-power.  The  average  daily  pay  for  a  man  is  2s.  8d.,  for 
a  woman,  Is.  8d.,  for  a  boy,  Is.  2^d.  As  a  result,  Belgium  had  in  1863,  as  compared 
with  1850,  nearly  doubled  both  the  amount  and  the  value  of  its  exports  of  coal, 
iron,  &c. 

1  Robert  Owen,  soon  after  1810,  not  only  maintained  the  necessity  of  a  limitation 
of  the  working  day  in  theory,  but  actually  introduced  the  10  hours'  day  into  his 
factory  at  New  Lanark.  This  was  laughed  at  as  a  communistic  Utopia ;  so  were  his 
"  Combination  of  children's  education  with  productive  labour,"  and  the  Co-operative 
Societies  of  working-men,  first  called  into  being  by  him.  To-day,  the  first  Utopia  is 
a  Factory  Act,  the  second  figures  as  an  official  phrase  in  aU  Factory  Acts,  the  thiid 
is  already  being  used  as  a  cloak  for  reactionary  humbug. 

2  Ure  :  "French  translation,  Philosophie  des  Llanufactures."  Paris,  1836,  Vol.  II., 
p.  39,  40,  67,  77,  &c. 

3  In  the  Compte  Rendu  of  the  International  Statistical  Congress  at  Paris,  1855,  it 
is  stated  :  "  The  French  law,  which  limits  the  length  of  daily  labour  in  factories  and 
workshops  to  12  hours,  does  not  confine  this  work  to  definite  fixed  hours.  For 
children's  labour  only  the  work-time  is  prescribed  as  between  5  a.m.  and  9  p.m. 
Therefore,  some  of  the  masters  use  the  right  which  this  fatal  silence  gives  them  to 
keep  their  works  going,  without  intermission,  day  in,  day  out,  possibly  with  the 
exception  of  Sunday.  For  this  puri^ose  they  use  two  different  sets  of  workers,  of 
whom  neither  is  in  the  workshoj)  more  than  12  hours  at  a  time,  but  the  work  of  the 
establishment  lasts  day  and  night.  The  law  is  satisfied,  but  is  humanity  ?  "  Besides 
"the  destructive  influence  of  night  labour  on  the  human  organism,"  stress  is  also 
laid  upon  "the  fatal  influence  of  the  association  of  the  two  sexes  by  night  in  the 
same  badly-lighted  workshops." 

*  "  For  instance,  there  is  within  my  district  one  occupier  who,  within  the  same  curti- 
lage, is  at  the  same  time  a  bleacher  and  dyer  under  the  Bleaching  and  Dyeing  Works 
Act,  a  printer  under  the  Print  Works  Act,  and  a  finisher  under  the  Factory  Act." 


The  Working  Day^  287 

principle  that  which  in  England  was  only  won  in  the  name 
of  children,  minors,  and  women,  and  has  been  only  recently' 
for  the  first  time  claimed  as  a  general  right.^ 

In  the  United  States  of  North  America,  every  independent 
movement  of  the  workers  was  paralysed  so  long  as  slavery  dis- 
figured a  part  of  the  Republic.  Labour  cannot  emancipate 
itself  in  the  white  skin  where  in  the  black  it  is  branded. 
But  out  of  the  death  of  slavery  a  new  life  at  once  arose.  The 
first  fruit  of  the  Civil  War  was  the  eight  hours'  agitation,  that 
ran  with  the  seven-leagued  boots  of  the  locomotive  from  the 
Atlantic  to  the  Pacific,  from  New  England  to  California.  The 
General  Congress  of  Labour  at  Baltimore  (August  16th,  1866) 
declared  :  "  The  first  and  great  necessity  of  the  present,  to  free 
the  labour  of  this  country  from  capitalistic  slavery,  is  the  pass- 
ing of  a  law  by  which  eight  hours  shall  be  the  normal  work- 
ing-day in  all  States  of  the  American  Union.  We  are  resolved 
to  put  forth  all  our  strength  until  this  glorious  result  is 
attained."  ^  At  the  same  time,  the  Congress  of  the  International 
Working  Men's  Association  at  Geneva,  on  the  proposition  of 
the  London  General  Council,  resolved  that  "the  limitation  of 
the  working-day  is  a  preliminary  condition  without  which 
all  further  attempts  at  improvement  and  emancipation  must 
prove  abortive.  .  .  .  the  Congress  proposes  eight  hours  as 
the  legal  limit  of  the  working-day." 

Thus  the  movement  of  the  working-class  on  both  sides  of 
the  Atlantic,  that  had  grown  instinctively  out  of  the  conditions 

(Report  of  Mr.  Baker,  in  Reports,  &c.,  for  October  31st,  1861,  p.  20.)  After  enume- 
ratiug  the  different  provisions  of  these  Acts,  and  the  complications  arising  from  them, 
Mr.  Baker  says  :  *'  It  will  hence  aj^^^ear  that  it  must  be  very  difficult  to  secure  the 
execution  of  these  three  Acts  of  Parliament  where  the  occupier  chooses  to  evade  the 
law."    But  what  is  assured  to  the  lawyers  by  this  is  lawsuits. 

^  Thus  the  Factory  Inspectors  at  last  venture  to  say:  "These  objections  (of 
capital  to  the  legal  limitation  of  the  working-day)  must  succumb  before  the  broad 
principle  of  the  rights  of  labour.  .  .  .  There  is  a  time  when  the  master's  right  in 
his  workman's  labour  ceases,  and  his  time  becomes  his  own,  even  if  there  were  no 
exhaustion  in  the  question."    (Reports,  &c.,  for  31st  Oct.,  1862,  p.  54.) 

^  "  AVe,  the  workers  of  Dunkirk,  declare  that  the  length  of  time  of  labour  required 
under  the  present  system  is  too  great,  and  that,  far  from  leaving  the  worker  time  for 
rest  and  education,  it  plunges  him  into  a  condition  of  servitude  but  little  better  than 
slavery.  That  is  why  we  decide  that  8  hours  are  enough  for  a  working-day,  and 
ought  to  be  legally  recognised  as  enough ;  why  we  call  to  our  help  that  powerful 
lever,  the  press  ;  .  .  .  and  why  we  shall  consider  all  those  that  refuse  us  this  help 
as  enemies  of  the  reform  of  labour  and  of  the  rights  of  the  labourer."  (Resolution  of 
the  Working  Men  of  Dunkiik,  New  York  State,  1866.) 


2  88  Capitalist  Production. 

of  production  themselves,  endorsed  the  words  of  the  English 
Factory  Inspector,  R  J.  Saunders :  "  Further  steps  towards  a 
reformation  of  society  can  never  be  carried  out  with  any  hope 
of  success,  unless  the  hours  of  labour  be  limited,  and  the  pre- 
scribed limit  strictly  enforced."  ^ 

It  must  be  acknowledged  that  our  labourer  comes  out  of  the 
process  of  production  other  than  he  entered.  In  the  market 
he  stood  as  owner  of  the  commodity  "  labour-power  "  face 
to  face  with  other  owners  of  commodities,  dealer  against 
dealer.  The  contract  by  which  he  sold  to  the  capitalist  his 
labour-power  proved,  so  to  say,  in  black  and  white  that  he  dis- 
posed of  himself  freely.  The  bargain  concluded,  it  is  dis- 
covered that  he  was  no  "  free  agent,"  that  the  time  for  which 
he  is  free  to  sell  his  labour-power  is  the  time  for  which  he  is 
forced  to  sell  it,^  that  in  fact  the  vampire  will  not  lose  its  hold 
on  him  "  so  long  as  there  is  a  muscle,  a  nerve,  a  drop  of  blood 
to  be  exploited."  *  For  "  protection  "  against  "  the  serpent  of 
their  agonies,"  the  labourers  must  put  their  heads  together, 
and,  as  a  class,  compel  the  passing  of  a  law,  an  all-powerful 
social  barrier  that  shall  prevent  the  very  workers  from  selling, 
by  voluntary  contract  with  capital,  themselves  and  their 
families  into  slavery  and  death."*  In  place  of  the  pompous 
catalogue  of  the  "  inalienable  rights  of  man  "  comes  the  modest 
Magna  Charta  of  a  legally  limited  working-day,  which  shall 
make  clear  '*  when  the  time  which  the  worker  sells  is  ended, 
and  when  his  own  begins." "     Quantum  mutatus  ab  illo  ! 

1  Reports,  &c.,  for  Oct.,  1848,  p.  112. 

2  "The  proceedings  (the  manoeuvres  of  capital,  e.gr,,  from  1848-50)  have  afforded, 
moreover,  incontrovertible  proof  of  the  fallacy  of  the  assertion  so  often  advanced,  that 
operatives  need  no  protection,  but  may  be  considered  as  free  agents  in  the  disposal  of 
the  only  property  which  they  possess — the  labour  of  their  hands  and  the  sweat  of  their 
brows."  (Reports,  &c.,  for  April  30th,  1850,  p.  45.)  "Free  labour  (if  so  it  may  be 
termed)  even  in  a  free  country,  requires  the  strong  arm  of  the  law  to  protect  it." 
(Reports,  &c.,  for  October  31st,  1864,  p.  34.)  "To  permit,  which  is  tantamount  to 
compelling  .  .  to  work  14  hours  a  day  with  or  without  meals,"  &c.  (Repts,,  &c., 
for  April  30th,  1863,  p,  40.)  s  Friedrich  Engels,  1.  c,  p.  5. 

-*  The  10  Hours'  Act  has,  in  the  branches  of  industry  that  come  under  it,  "put  an 
end  to  the  premature  decrepitude  of  the  former  long-hour  workers."  (Reports.,  &c., 
for  31st  Oct.,  1859,  p,  47.)  "  Capital  (in  factories)  can  never  be  employed  in  keep- 
ing the  machinery  in  motion  beyond  a  limited  time,  without  certain  injury  to  the 
health  and  morals  of  the  labourers  employed ;  and  they  are  not  in  a  position  to 
l^rotect  themselves."    (1.  c,  p.  8.) 

^  "  A  still  greater  boon  is  the  distinction  at  last  made  clear  between  the  worker's 
own  time  and  his  master's.     The  worker  knows  now  when  that  whicli  he  sells  is 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus- Value,  289 

CHAPTER  XL 

RATE  AND  MASS   OF   SURPLUS-VALUE. 

In  this  chapter,  as  hitherto,  the  value  of  labour-power,  and 
therefore  the  part  of  the  working-day  necessary  for  the  repro- 
duction or  maintenance  of  that  labour-power,  are  supposed  to 
be  given,  constant  magnitudes. 

This  premised,  with  the  rate,  the  mass  is  at  the  same  time 
given  of  the  surplus- value  that  the  individual  labourer  furnishes 
to  the  capitalist  in  a  definite  period  of  time.  If,  e.g.^  the 
necessary  labour  amounts  to  6  hours  daily,  expressed  in  a 
quantum  of  gold  ^=  3  shillings,  then  8s.  is  the  daily  value  of 
one  labour-power  or  the  value  of  the  capital  advanced  in  the 
buying  of  one  labour-power.  If,  further,  the  rate  of  surplus- 
value  be  =  100  %,  this  variable  capital  of  8s.  produces  a  mass 
of  surplus- value  of  3s.,  or  the  labourer  supplies  daily  a  mass  of 
surplus-labour  equal  to  6  hours. 

But  the  variable  capital  of  a  capitalist  is  the  expression  in 
money  of  the  total  value  of  all  the  labour-powers  that  he 
employs  simultaneously.  Its  value  is,  therefore,  equal  to  the 
average  value  of  one  labour-power,  multiplied  by  the  number 
of  labour-powers  employed.  With  a  given  value  of  labour- 
power,  therefore,  the  magnitude  of  the  variable  capital  varies 
directly  as  the  number  of  labourers  employed  simultaneously. 
If  the  daily  value  of  one  labour-power  =  3s.,  then  a  capital  of 
300s.  must  be  advanced  in  order  to  exploit  daily  100  labour- 
powers,  of  n  times  3s.,  in  order  to  exploit  daily  n  labour- 
powers. 

ended,  and  when  his  own  begins  ;  and  by  possessing  a  sure  foreknowledge  of  this,  is 
enabled  to  pre-arrange  his  own  minutes  for  liis  own  purposes,"  (1,  c,  p.  52,)  "  By 
making  them  masters  of  their  own  time  (the  Factory  Acts)  have  given  them  a  moral 
energy  which  is  directing  them  to  the  eventual  possession  of  political  power"  (1,  c,, 
p.  47).  With  suppressed  irony,  and  in  very  well  weighed  words,  the  Factory  In- 
spectors hint  that  the  actual  law  also  frees  the  capitalist  from  some  of  the  brutality 
natural  to  a  man  who  is  a  mere  embodiment  of  capital,  and  that  it  has  given  him 
time  for  a  little  "culture."  "Formerly  the  master  had  no  time  for  anything  but 
money  j  the  servant  had  no  time  for  anything  but  labour  "  (1.  c,  p,  48), 


290  Capitalist  Production. 

In  the  same  way,  if  a  variable  capital  of  3s.,  being  the  daily 
value  of  one  labour-power;  produce  a  daily  surplus- value  of  3s., 
a  variable  capital  of  300s.  will  produce  a  daily  surplus-value  of 
300s.,  and  one  of  n  times  3s.  a  daily  surplus-value  of  n  x  3s. 
The  mass  of  the  surplus-value  produced  is  therefore  equal  to 
the  surplus-value  which  the  working-day  of  one  labourer 
supplies  multiplied  by  the  number  of  labourers  employed. 
But  as  further  the  mass  of  surplus- value  which  a  single  labourer 
produces,  the  value  of  labour-power  being  given,  is  determined 
by  the  rate  of  the  surplus- value,  this  law  follows :  the  mass  of 
the  surplus- value  pi'oduced  is  equal  to  the  amount  of  the 
variable  capital  advanced,  multiplied  by  the  rate  of  surplus- 
value  ;  in  other  words :  it  is  determined  by  the  compound  ratio 
between  the  number  of  labour-powers  exploited  simultaneously 
by  the  same  capitalist  and  the  degree,  of  exploitation  of  each 
individual  labour-power. 

Let  the  mass  of  the  surplus- value  be  S,  the  surplus- value 
supplied  by  the  individual  labourer  in  the  average  day  s,  the 
variable  capital  daily  advanced  in  the  purchase  of  one  individual 
labour-power  v,  the  sum  total  of  the  variable  capital  V,  the 
value  of  an  average  labour-power  P,  its  degree  of  exploitation 
t  (nSSSboOr)  ^^^  ^^  number  of  labourers  employed  n ;  we 
have: 

(    1  xV 
S=  {   V 

(  Px  I'  X  n 

It  is  always  supposed,  not  only  that  the  value  of  an  average 
labour-power  is  constant,  but  that  the  labourers  employed  by 
a  capitalist  are  reduced  to  average  labourers.  There  are  ex- 
ceptional cases  in  which  the  surplus- value  produced  does  not 
increase  in  proportion  to  the  number  of  labourers  exploited, 
but  then  the  value  of  the  labour-power  does  not  remain  con- 
stant. 

In  the  production  of  a  definite  mass  of  surplus-value,  there- 
fore, the  decrease  of  one  factor  may  be  compensated  by  the  in- 
crease of  the  other.  If  the  variable  capital  diminishes,  and  at 
the  same  time  the  rate  of  surplus-value  increases  in  the  same 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus- Value,  291 

ratio,  the  mass  of  surplus- value  produced  remains  unaltered. 
If  on  our  earlier  assumption  the  capitalist  must  advance  300s., 
in  order  to  exploit  100  labourers  a  day,  and  if  the  rate  of 
surplus-value  amounts  to  oO  %,  this  variable  capital  of  800s. 
yields  a  surplus-value  of  150s.  or  of  100  x  3  working  hours.  If 
the  rate  of  surplus-value  doubles,  or  the  working-day,  instead 
of  being  extended  from  6  to  9,  is  extended  from  6  to  12  hours 
and  at  the  same  time  variable  capital  is  lessened  by  half,  and 
reduced  to  150s.,  it  yields  also  a  surplus- value  of  150s.  or  50  x 
6  working  hours.  Diminution  of  the  variable  capital  may  there- 
fore be  compensated  by  a  proportionate  rise  in  the  degree  of 
exploitation  of  labour-power,  or  the  decrease  in  the  number  of 
the  labourers  employed  by  a  proportionate  extension  of  the 
working-day.  Within  certain  limits  therefore  the  supply  of 
labour  exploitable  by  capital  is  independent  of  the  supply  of 
labourers.^  On  the  contrary,  a  fall  in  the  rate  of  surplus-value 
leaves  unaltered  the  mass  of  the  surplus-value  produced,  if  the 
amount  of  the  variable  capital,  or  number  of  the  labourers  em- 
ployed, increases  in  the  same  proportion. 

Nevertheless,  the  compensation  of  a  decrease  in  the  number 
of  labourers  employed,  or  of  the  amount  of  variable  capital 
advanced,  by  a  rise  in  the  rate  of  surplus- value,  or  by  the 
lengthening  of  the  working-day,  has  impassable  limits.  What- 
ever the  value  of  labour-power  may  be,  whether  the  working 
time  necessary  for  the  maintenance  of  the  labourer  is  2  or  10 
hours,  the  total  value  that  a  labourer  can  produce,  day  in,  day 
out,  is  always  less  than  the  value  in  which  24  hours  of  labour 
are  embodied,  less  than  12s.,  if  12s.  is  the  money  expression  for 
24  hours  of  realized  labour.  In  our  former  assumption,  accord- 
ing to  which  6  working  hours  are  daily  necessary  in  order  to 
reproduce  the  labour-power  itself  or  to  replace  the  value  of  the 
capital  advanced  in  its  purchase,  a  variable  capital  of  1500s.,  that 
employs  500  labourers  at  a  rate  of  surplus-value  of  100  %  with 
a  12  hours'  working-day,  produces  daily  a  surplus- value  of  1500s. 
or  of  6  X  500  working  hours.     A  capital  of  300s.  that  employs 

1  This  elementary  law  appears  to  be  unknown  to  the  vulgar  economists,  who,  upside- 
down  Archimedes,  in  the  determination  of  the  market-])rice  of  labour  by  supply  and 
demand,  imagine  they  have  found  the  fulcrum  by  means  of  which,  not  to  move  the 
world,  but  to  stop  its  motion. 


292  Capitalist  Pivduction. 

100  labourers  a  day  with  a  rate  of  surplus-value  of  200  %  or 
with  a  working-day  of  18  hours,  produces  only  a  mass  of 
surplus-value  of  600s.  or  12  x  100  working  hours;  and  its  total 
value-product,  the  equivalent  of  the  variable  capital  advanced 
plus  the  surplus-value,  can,  day  in,  day  out,  never  reach  the  sum 
of  1200s.  or  24  x  100  workinor  hours.  The  absolute  limit  of 
the  average  working-day — this  being  by  Nature  always  less  than 
24  liours — sets  an  absolute  limit  to  the  compensation  of  a  re- 
duction of  variable  capital  by  a  higher  rate  of  surplus- value,  or 
of  the  decrease  of  the  number  of  labourers  exploited  by  f!»^igher 
degree  of  exploitation  of  labour-power.  This  palpable  law  is 
of  importance  for  the  clearing  up  of  many  phenomena,  arising 
from  a  tendency  (to  be  worked  out  later  on)  of  capital  to  re- 
duce as  much  as  possible  the  number  of  labourers  employed  by 
it,  or  its  variable  constituent  transformed  into  labour-power,  in 
contradiction  to  its  other  tendency  to  produce  the  greatest 
possible  mass  of  surplus- value.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  mass 
of  labour-power  employed,  or  the  amount  of  variable  capital, 
increases,  but  not  in  proportion  to  the  fall  in  the  rate  of  surplus- 
value,  the  mass  of  the  surplus-value  produced,  falls. 

A  third  law  results  from  the  determination,  of  the  mass  of 
the  surplus- value  produced,  by  the  two  factors  :  rate  of  surplus- 
value  and  amount  of  variable  capital  advanced.  The  rate  of 
surplus-value,  or  the  degree  of  exploitation  of  labour-power, 
and  the  value  of  labour-power,  or  the  amount  of  necessary 
working  time  being  given,  it  is  self-evident  that  the  greater  the 
variable  capital,  the  greater  would  be  the  mass  of  the  value 
produced  and  of  the  surplus-value.  If  the  limit  of  the  working- 
day  is  given,  and  also  the  limit  of  its  necessary  constituent,  the 
mass  of  value  and  surplus-value  that  an  individual  capitalist 
produces,  is  clearly  exclusively  dependent  on  the  mass  of  labour 
that  he  sets  in  motion.  But  this,  under  the  conditions  supposed 
above,  depends  on  the  mass  of  labour-power,  or  the  number  of 
labourers  whom  he  exploits,  and  this  number  in  its  turn  is 
determined  by  the  amount  of  the  variable  capital  advanced. 
With  a  given  rate  of  surplus -value,  and  a  given  value  of  labour- 
power,  therefore,  the  masses  of  surplus-value  produced  vary 
directly  as   the  amounts  of  the   variable   capitals   advanced. 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus- Vahie.  293 

Now  we  know  that  the  capitalist  divides  his  capital  into  two 
parts.  One  part  he  lays  out  in  means  of  production.  This  is 
the  constant  part  of  his  capital.  The  other  part  he  lays  out  in 
living  labour-power.  This  part  forms  his  variable  capital.  On 
the  basis  of  the  same  mode  of  social  production,  the  division  of 
capital  into  constant  and  variable  differs  in  different  branches 
of  production,  and  within  the  same  branch  of  production,  too, 
this  relation  changes  with  changes  in  the  technical  conditions 
and  in  the  social  combinations  of  the  processes  of  production. 
But  in  whatever  proportion  a  given  capital  breaks  up  into  a 
constant  and  a  variable  part,  whether  the  latter  is  to  the  former 
as  1  :  2  or  1 :  10  or  1 :  X,  the  law  just  laid  down  is  not  affected 
by  this.  For,  according  to  our  previous  analysis,  the  value  of 
the  constant  capital  reappears  in  the  value  of  the  product,  but 
does  not  enter  into  the  newly  produced  value,  the  newly 
created  value-product.  To  employ  1000  spinners,  more  raw 
material,  spindles,  fee,  are,  of  course,  required,  than  to  employ 
100.  The  value  of  these  additional  means  of  production  how- 
ever, may  rise,  fall,  remain  unaltered,  be  large  or  small ;  it  has 
no  influence  on  the  process  of  creation  of  surplus-value  by 
means  of  the  labour-powers  that  put  them  in  motion.  The  law 
demonstrated  above  now,  therefore,  takes  this  form  :  the  masses 
of  value  and  of  surplus-value  produced  by  different  capitals — 
the  value  of  labour-power  being  given  and  its  degree  of  ex- 
ploitation being  equal — vary  directly  as  the  amounts  of  the 
variable  constituents  of  these  capitals,  ^.e.,  as  their  constituents 
transformed  into  living  labour-power. 

This  law  clearly  contradicts  all  experience  based  on  appear- 
ance. Every  one  knows  that  a  cotton  spinner,  who,  reckoning 
the  percentage  on  the  whole  of  his  applied  capital,  employs 
much  constant  and  little  variable  capital,  does  not,  on  account 
of  this,  pocket  less  profit  or  surplus-value  than  a  baker,  who 
relatively  sets  in  motion  much  variable  and  little  constant 
capital.  For  the  solution  of  this  apparent  contradiction,  many 
intermediate  terms  are  as  yet  wanted,  as  from  the  standpoint 
of  elementary  algebra  many  intermediate  terms  are  wanted  to 
understand  that  J  may  represent  an  actual  magnitude.  Classical 
economy,  although  not  formulating  the  law,  holds  instinctively 


294  Capitalist  Production. 

to  it,  because  it  is  a  necessary  consequence  of  the  general  law 
of  value.  It  tries  to  rescue  the  law  from  collision  with 
contradictory  phenomena  by  a  vioieut  abstraction.  It  will  be 
seen  later^  how  the  school  of  Ricardo  has  come  to  grief  over 
this  stumbling-block.  Vulgar  economy  which,  indeed,  "  has 
really  learnt  nothing,"  here  as  everywhere  sticks  to  appearances 
in  opposition  to  the  law  which  regulates  and  explains  them. 
In  opposition  to  Spinoza,  it  believes  that  "  ignorance  is  a  suffi- 
cient reason." 

The  labour  which  is  set  in  motion  by  the  total  capital  of  a 
society,  day  in,  day  out,  may  be  regarded  as  a  single  collective 
working-day.  If,  e.g.^  the  number  of  labourers  is  a  million,  and 
the  average  working-day  of  a  labourer  is  10  hours,  the  social 
working-day  consists  often  million  hours.  With  a  given  length 
of  this  working-day,  whether  its  limits  are  fixed  physically 
or  socially,  the  mass  of  surplus-value  can  only  be  increased  by 
increasing  the  number  of  labourers,  i.e.,  of  the  labouring 
population.  The  growth  of  population  here  forms  the  mathe- 
matical limit  to  the  production  of  surplus-value  by  the  total 
social  capital.  On  the  contrary,  with  a  given  amount  of 
population,  this  limit  is  formed  by  the  possible  lengthening  of 
the  working-day.^  It  will,  however,  be  seen  in  the  following 
chapter  that  this  law  only  holds  for  the  form  of  surplus-value 
dealt  with  up  to  the  present. 

From  the  treatment  of  the  production  of  surplus-value,  so 
far,  it  follows  that  not  every  sum  of  money,  or  of  value,  is  at 
pleasure  transformable  into  capital.  To  effect  this  transforma- 
tion, in  fact,  a  certain  minimum  of  money  or  of  exchange- value 
must  be  presupposed  in  the  hands  of  the  individual  possessor 
of  money  or  commodities.  The  minimum  of  variable  capital  is 
the  cost  price  of  a  single  labour-power,  employed  the  whole 
year  through,  day  in,  day  out,  for  the  production  of  surplus- 
value.     If  this  labourer  were  in  possession  of  his  own  means 

1  Further  particulars  will  be  given  in  Book  IV. 

2  "  The  labour,  that  is  the  economic  time,  of  society,  is  a  given  portion,  say  ten 

hours  a  day  of  a  million  of  people,  or  ten  million  hours Capital  has  its 

boundary  of  increase.  This  boundary  may,  at  any  given  period,  be  attained  in  the 
actual  extent  of  economic  time  employed."  ('  An  Essay  on  the  Political  Economy  of 
Nations."    London,  1821,  pp.  47,  49.) 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus-  Value.  295 

of  production,  and  were  satisfied  to  live  as  a  labourer,  he  need 
not  work  beyond  the  time  necessary  for  the  reproduction  of 
his  means  of  subsistence,  say  8  hours  a  day.  He  would,  besides, 
only  require  the  means  of  production  sufficient  for  8  working 
hours.  The  capitalist,  on  the  other  hand,  who  makes  him  do, 
besides  these  8  hours,  say  4  hours'  surplus-labour,  requires  an 
additional  sum  of  money  for  furnishing  the  additional  means 
of  production.  On  our  supposition,  however,  he  would  have  to 
employ  two  labourers  in  order  to  live,  on  the  surplus-value 
appropriated  daily,  as  well  as,  and  no  better  than  a  labourer, 
^.e.,  to  be  able  to  satisfy  his  necessary  wants.  In  this  case  the 
mere  maintenance  of  life  would  be  the  end  of  his  production, 
not  the  increase  of  wealth ;  but  this  latter  is  implied  in 
capitalist  production.  That  he  may  live  only  twice  as  well 
as  an  ordinary  labourer,  and  besides  turn  half  of  the  surplus- 
value  produced  into  capital,  he  would  have  to  raise,  with  the 
number  of  labourers,  the  minimum  of  the  capital  advanced  8 
times.  Of  course  he  can,  like  his  labourer,  take  to  work  him- 
self, participate  directly  in  the  process  of  production,  but  he  is 
then  only  a  hj^brid  between  capitalist  and  labourer,  a  "  small 
master."  A  certain  stage  of  capitalist  production  necessitates 
that  the  capitalist  be  able  to  devote  the  whole  of  the  time 
during  which  he  functions  as  a  capitalist,  i.e.y  as  personified 
capital,  to  the  appropriation  and  therefore  control  of  the  labour 
of  others,  and  to  the  selling  of  the  products  of  this  labour.^ 
The  guilds  of  the  middle  ages  therefore  tried  to  prevent  by 
force  the  transformation  of  the  master  of  a  trade  into  a 
capitalist,  by  limiting  the  number  of  labourers  that  could  be 

1  "  The  farmer  cannot  rely  on  his  own  labour,  and  if  he  does,  I  will  maintain  that 
he  is  a  loser  by  it.  His  employment  should  be  a  general  attention  to  the  whole  :  his 
thresher  must  be  watched,  or  he  will  soon  lose  his  wages  in  corn  not  threshed  out ; 
his  mowers,  reapers,  &c.,  must  be  looked  after;  he  must  constantly  go  round  his 
fences  ;  he  must  see  there  is  no  neglect ;  which  would  be  the  case  if  he  was  confined 
to  any  one  spot."  ("  An  Inquiry  into  the  connection  between  the  Price  of  Provisions 
and  the  Size  of  Farms,  &c.  By  a  Farmer."  London,  1773,  p.  12.)  This  book  is  very 
interesting.  In  it  the  genesis  of  the  "capitalist  farmer"  or  "merchant  farmer,"  as 
he  is  explicitly  called,  may  be  studied,  and  his  self-glorification  at  the  expense  of  the 
small  farmer  who  has  only  to  do  with  bare  subsistence,  be  noted.  "The  class  of 
capitalists  are  from  the  first  partially,  and  they  become  ultimately  completely,  dis- 
charged from  the  necessity  of  the  manual  labour."  ("  Text-book  of  Lectures  on  the 
Political  Economy  of  Nations.  By  the  Rev.  Richard  Jones."  Hertford,  1852. 
Lecture  III.  p.  39.) 


296  Capitalist  Production. 

employed  by  one  master  within  a  very  small  maximum.  The 
possessor  of  money  or  commodities  actually  turns  into  a 
capitalist  in  such  cases  only  where  the  minimum  sum  advanced 
for  production  greatly  exceeds  the  maximum  of  the  middle 
ages.  Here,  as  in  natural  science,  is  shown  the  correctness  of 
the  law  discovered  by  Hegel  (in  his  "Logic"),  that  merely 
quantitative  differences  beyond  a  certain  point  pass  into 
qualitative  changes.^ 

The  minimum  of  the  sum  of  value  that  the  individual  pos- 
sessor of  money  or  commodities  must  command,  in  order  to 
metamorphose  himself  into  a  capitalist,  changes  with  the 
dijfferent  stages  of  development  of  capitalist  production,  and 
is  at  given  stages  different  in  different  spheres  of  production, 
according  to  their  special  and  technical  conditions.  Certain 
spheres  of  production  demand,  even  at  the  very  outset  of  capi- 
talist production,  a  minimum  of  capital  that  is  not  as  yet 
found  in  the  hands  of  single  individuals.  This  gives  rise  partly 
to  state  subsidies  to  private  persons,  as  in  France  in  the  time  of 
Colbert,  and  as  in  many  German  states  up  to  our  own  epoch ; 
partly  to  the  formation  of  societies  with  legal  monopoly  for  the 
exploitation  of  certain  branches  of  industry  and  commerce,  the 
fore-runners  of  our  modern  joint-stock  companies.^ 

Within  the  process  of  production,  as  we  have  §een,  capital 
acquired  the  command  over  labour,  i.e.,  over  functioning  labour- 
power  or  the  labourer  himself  Personified  capital,  the  capi- 
talist takes  care  that  the  labourer  does  his  work  regularly  and 
with  the  proper  degree  of  intensity. 

Capital  further  developed  into   a  coercive  relation,  which 

1  The  molecular  theory  of  modern  chemistry  first  scientifically  worked  out  by 
Laurent  and  Gerhardt  rests  on  no  other  law.  (Addition  to  3rd  Edition, )  For  the  ex- 
planation of  this  statement,  which  is  not  very  clear  to  non-chemists,  we  remark  that 
the  author  speaks  here  of  the  homologous  series  of  carbon  compounds,  first  so  named 
by  C.  Gerhardt  in  1843,  each  series  of  which  has  its  own  general  algebraic  formula. 
Thus  the  series  of  paraffins :  QP-  H2n  +2^  that  of  the  normal  alcohols  :  C^^  H2n  +  2o  ; 
of  the  normal  fatty  acids  :  0°-  H2n  02  and  many  others.  In  the  above  examples,  by 
the  simply  quantitative  addition  of  C  H^  to  the  molecular  formula,  a  qualitatively 
different  body  is  each  time  formed.  On  the  share  (overestimated  by  Marx)  of  Laurent 
and  Gerhardt  in  the  determination  of  this  important  fact  see  Kopp,  "Entwicklung 
der  Ohemle."  Miinchen,  1873,  pp,  709,  716,  and  Schorlemmer,  **  Rise  and  Progress 
of  Organic  Chemistry,"    London,  1879,  p.  54.— Ed. 

2  Martin  Luther  calls  these  kinds  of  institutions  :  "The  Company  Monopolia." 


\ 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus- Value,  297 

compels  the  working  class  to  do  more  work  than  the  narrow 
round  of  its  own  life- wants  prescribes.  As  a  producer  of  the 
activity  of  others,  as  a  pumper-out  of  surplus-labour  and  ex- 
ploiter of  labour-power,  it  surpasses  in  energy,  disregard  of 
bounds,  recklessness  and  eflB.ciency,  all  earlier  systems  of  pro- 
duction based  on  directly  compulsory  labour. 

At  first,  capital  subordinates  labour  on  the  basis  of  the  tech- 
nical conditions  in  which  it  historically  finds  it.  It  does  not, 
therefore,  change  immediately  the  mode  of  production.  The 
production  of  surplus-value — in  the  form  hitherto  considered 
by  us — by  means  of  simple  extension  of  the  working-day, 
proved,  therefore,  to  be  independent  of  any  change  in  the 
mode  of  production  itself.  It  was  not  less  active  in  the  old- 
fashioned  bakeries  than  in  the  modern  cotton  factories. 

If  we  consider  the  process  of  production  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  simple  labour-process,  the  labourer  stands  in  relation 
to  the  means  of  production,  not  in  their  quality  as  capital,  but 
as  the  mere  means  and  material  of  his  own  intelligent  pro- 
ductive activity.  In  tanning,  e.g.^  he  deals  with  the  skins  as 
his  simple  object  of  labour.  It  is  not  the  capitalist  whose  skin 
he  tans.  But  it  is  different  as  soon  as  we  deal  with  the  process 
of  production  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  process  of  creation 
of  surplus-value.  The  means  of  production  are  at  once  changed 
into  means  for  the  absorption  of  the  labour  of  others.  It  is  now 
no  longer  the  labourer  that  employs  the  means  of  production, 
but  the  means  of  production  that  employ  ^e  labourer]  In^  \ 
stead  of  being  consumed  by  him  as  material  elements  of  his 
productive  activity,  they  consume  him  as  the  ferment  neces- 
sary to  their  own  life-process,  and  the  life-process  of  capital 
consists  only  in  its  movement  as  value  constantly  expanding, 
constantly  multiplying  itself.  Furnaces  and  workshops  that 
stand  idle  by  night,  and  absorb  no  living  labour,  are  "  a  mere 
loss"  to  the  capitalist.  Hence,  furnaces  and  workshops  con- 
stitute lawful  claims  upon  the  night-labour  of  the  workpeople. 
The  simple  transformation  of  money  into  the  material  factors 
of  the  process  of  production,  into  means  of  production,  trans- 
forms the  latter  into  a  title  and  a  right  to  the  labour  and 
surplus-labour  of  others.    An  example  will  show,  in  conclusion. 


298  Capitalist  Production. 

how  this  sophistication,  peculiarto  and  characteristic  of  capitalist 
production,  this  complete  inversion  of  the  relation  between  dead 
and  living  labour,  between  value  and  the  force  that  creates 
value,  mirrors  itself  in  the  consciousness  of  capitalists.  During 
the  revolt  of  the  English  factory  lords  between  1848  and  1850, 
"  the  head  of  one  of  the  oldest  and  most  respectable  houses  in 
the  West  of  Scotland,  Messrs.  Carlile  Sons  k>  Co.,  of  the  linen 
and  cotton  thread  factory  at  Paisley,  a  company  which  has  now 
existed  for  about  a  century,  which  was  in  operation  in  1752, 
and  four  generations  of  the  same  family  have  conducted  it "  .  .  . 
this  "  very  intelligent  gentleman  "  then  wrote  a  letter^  in  the 
"Glasgow  Daily  Mail"  of  April  25th,  1849,  with  the  title, 
"The  relay  system,"  in  which  among  other  things  the  following 
grotesquely  naive  passage  occurs :  "  Let  us  now  .  .  .  see  what 
evils  will  attend  the  limiting  to  10  hours  the  working  of  the 
factory.  .  .  .  They  amount  to  the  most  serious  damage  to 
the  mill-owner's  prospects  and  property.  If  he  {i.e.,  his  "hands  ") 
worked  12  hours  before,  and  is  limited  to  10,  then  every  12 
machines  or  spindles  in  his  establishment  shrink  to  10,  and 
should  the  works  be  disposed  of,  they  v/ill  be  valued  only  as  10, 
so  that  a  sixth  part  would  thus  be  deducted  from  the  value  of 
every  factory  in  the  country."  ^ 

To  tliis  West  of  Scotland  bourgeois  brain,  inheriting  the 
accumulated  capitalistic  qualities  of  "four  generations,"  the 
value  of  the  means  of  production,  spindles,  &;c.  is  so  inseparably 
mixed  up  with  their  property,  as  capital,  to  expand  their  own 
value,  and  to  swallow  up  daily  a  definite  quantity  of  the  un- 
paid labour  of  others,  that  the  head  of  the  firm  of  Carlile  &  Co. 
actually  imagines  that  if  he  sells  his  factory,  not  only  will  the 
value  of  the  spindles  be  paid  to  him,  but,  in  addition,  their 
power  of  annexing  surplus- value,  not  only  the  labour  which  is 
embodied  in  them,  and  is  necessary  to  the  production  of  spindles 

i  Reports  of  Insp.  of  Fact.,  April  30th,  1849,  p.  59. 

2  1.  c,  p.  60.  Factory  Inspector  Stuart,  himself  a  Scotchman,  and  in  contrast  to 
the  English  Factory  Inspectors,  quite  taken  captive  by  the  capitalistic  method  of 
thinking,  remarks  expressly  on  this  letter  which  he  incorporates  in  his  report  that  it 
is  *'  the  most  useful  of  the  communications  which  any  of  the  factory-owners  working 
with  relays  have  given  to  those  engaged  in  the  same  trade,  and  which  is  the  most 
calculated  to  remove  the  prejudices  of  such  of  them  as  have  scruples  respecting  any 
change  of  the  arrangement  of  the  hours  of  work. " 


Rate  and  Mass  of  Surplus- Value.  299 

of  this  kind,  but  also  the  surph.is-labour  which  they  help  to 
pump  out  daily  from  the  brave  Scots  of  Paisley,  and  for  that 
very  reason  he  thinks  that  with  the  shortening  of  the  working- 
day  by  2  hours,  the  selling-price  of  12  spinning  machines 
dwindles  to  that  of  10  1 


PART  IV. 
PRODUCTION  OF  RELATIVE  SURPLUS-VALUE. 


CHAPTER  XII. 

THE  CONCEPT  OF  RELATIVE  SURPLUS-VALUE. 

That  portion  of  the  working-day  which  merely  produces 
an  equivalent  for  the  value  paid  by  the  capitalist  for  his 
labour-power,  has,  up  to  this  point,  been  treated  by  us  as 
a  constant  magnitude ;  and  such  in  fact  it  is,  under  given 
conditions  of  production  and  at  a  given  stage  in  the  econo- 
mical development  of  society.  Beyond  this,  his  necessary 
labour-time,  the  labourer,  we  saw,  could  continue  to  work 
for  2,  3,  4,  6,  &c.,  hours.  The  rate  of  surplus-value  and 
the  length  of  the  working  day  depended  on  the  magni- 
tude of  this  prolongation.  Though  the  necessary  labour- 
time  was  constant,  we  saw,  on  the  other  hand,  that  the 
total  working-day  was  variable.  Now  suppose  we  have  a 
working-day  whose  length,  and  whose  apportionment  be- 
tween necessary  labour  and  surplus-labour,  are  given.     Let 

the  whole  line  a  c,  a b — c  represent,  for  example, 

a  working-day  of  12  hours;   the   portion   of  a  b  10  hours 


The  Concept  of  Relative  Stirplus-Vahte.       30 1 

of  necessary  labour,  and  the  portion  b  c  2  hours  of  surplus- 
labour.  How  now  can  the  production  of  surplus-value  be 
increased,  i.e.,  how  can  the  surplus-labour  be  prolonged,  with- 
out, or  independently  of,  any  prolongation  of  a  c  ? 

Although  the  length  of  a  c  is  given,  b  c  appears  to  be  capable 
of  prolongation,  if  not  by  extension  beyond  its  end  c,  which  is 
also  the  end  of  the  working  day  a  c,  yet,  at  all  events,  by  push- 
ing back  its  starting  point  b  in  the  direction  of  a.  Assume 
that  b' — b  in  the  line  a  V  b  c  is  equal  to  half  of  b  c 

a b' — b c 

or  to  one  hour's  labour-time.  If  now,  in  a  c,  the  working  day 
of  12  hours,  we  move  the  point  b  to  V,  b  c  becomes  b'  c ;  the 
surplus-labour  increases  by  one  half,  from  2  hours  to  3  hours, 
although  the  working  day  remains  as  before  at  12  hours. 
This  extension  of  the  surplus  labour-time  from  b  c  to  b'  c,  from 
2  hours  to  3  liours,  is,  however,  evidently  impossible,  without  a 
simultaneous  contraction  of  the  necessary  labour-time  from 
a  b  into  a  V,  from  10  hours  to  9  hours.  The  prolongation  of 
the  surplus-labour  would  correspond  to  a  shortening  of  the 
necessary  labour ;  or  a  portion  of  the  labour-time  previously 
consumed,  in  reality,  for  the  labourer's  own  benefit,  would  be 
converted  into  labour-time  for  the  benefit  of  the  capitalist. 
There  would  be  an  alteration,  not  in  the  length  of  the  working 
day,  but  in  its  division  into  necessary  labour-time  and  surplus 
labour-time. 

On  the  other  hand,  it  is  evident  that  the  duration  of  the 
surplus-labour  is  given,  when  the  length  of  the  working  day, 
and  the  value  of  labour-power,  are  given.  The  value  of 
labour-power,  i.e.,  the  labour-time  requisite  to  produce  labour- 
power,  determines  the  ]i;bour-time  necessary  for  the  repro- 
duction of  that  value.  If  one  working  hour  be  embodied  in 
sixpence,  and  the  value  of  a  day's  labour-power  be  five  shillings, 
the  labourer  must  work  10  hours  a  day,  in  order  to  replace 
the  value  paid  by  capital  for  his  labour-power,  or  to  produce 
an  equivalent  for  the  value  of  his  daily  necessary  means  of  sub- 
sistence. Given  the  value  of  these  means  of  subsistence,  the 
value  of  his  labour-power  is  given ;^  and  given  the  value  of  his 

1  The  value  of  his  average  daily  wages  is  determined  by  what  the  labourer  requires 


302  Capitalist  Production. 

labour-power,  the  duration  of  his  necessary  labour-time  is  given. 
The  duration  of  the  surplus-labour,  however,  is  arrived  at,  by 
subtracting  the  necessary  labour-time  from  the  total  working 
day.  Ten  hours  subtracted  from  twelve,  leave  two,  and  it  is 
not  easy  to  see,  how,  under  the  given  conditions,  the  surplus- 
labour  can  possibly  be  prolonged  beyond  two  hours.  No 
doubt,  the  capitalist  can,  instead  of  five  shillings,  pay  the 
labourer  four  shillings  and  sixpence  or  even  less.  For  the  re- 
production of  this  value  of  four  shillings  and  sixpence,  nine 
hours  labour-time  would  suffice  ;  and  consequently  three  hours 
of  surplus-labour,  instead  of  two,  would  accrue  to  the  capitalist, 
and  the  surplus-value  would  rise  from  one  shilling  to  eighteen- 
pence.  This  result,  however,  would  be  obtained  only  by  lowering 
the  wages  of  the  labourer  below  the  value  of  his  labour-power. 
With  the  four  shillings  and  sixpence  which  he  produces  in  nine 
hours,  he  commands  one-tenth  less  of  the  necessaries  of  life  than 
before,  and  consequently  the  proper  reproduction  of  his  labour- 
power  is  crippled.  The  surplus-labour  would  in  this  case  be 
prolonged  only  by  an  overstepping  of  its  normal  limits ;  its 
domain  would  be  extended  only  by  a  usurpation  of  part  of  the 
domain  of  necessary  labour-time.  Despite  the  important  part 
which  this  method  plays  in  actual  practice,  we  are  excluded 
from  considering  it  in  this  place,  by  our  assumption,  that  all 
commodities,  including  labour-power,  are  bought  and  sold  at 
their  full  value.  Granted  this,  it  follows  that  the  labour-time 
necessary  for  the  production  of  labour-power,  or  for  the  repro- 
duction of  its  value,  cannot  be  lessened  by  a  fall  in  the 
labourer's  wages  below  the  value  of  his  labour-power,  but  only 
by  a  fall  in  this  value  itself.  Given  the  length  of  the  working 
day,  the  prolongation  of  the  surplus-labour  must  of  necessity 

*'  so  as  to  live,  labour,  and  generate."  (Wm.  Petty :  '  *  Political  Anatomy  of  Ireland, " 
1672,  p.  64.)  "  The  price  of  Labour  is  always  constituted  of  the  price  of  necessaries 
.  .  .  whenever  ....  the  labouring  man's  wages  will  not,  suitably  to  his  low  rank  and 
station,  as  a  labouring  man,  support  such  a  family  as  is  often  the  lot  of  many  of  them 
to  have,"  he  does  not  receive  proper  wages.  (J.  Vanderlint,  1.  c.  p.  15.)  *'  Le  simple 
ouvrier,  qui  n'a  que  ses  bras  et  son  Industrie,  n'a  rien  qu'autant  qu'il  parvient  ^ 
vendre  £t  d'autres  sa  peine.  .  .  En  tout  genre  de  travail  il  doit  arriver,  et  il  arrive  en 
effet,  que  le  salaire  de  1' ouvrier  se  borne  a  ce  qui  lui  est  necessaire  pour  lui  procurer 
sa  subsistance. "  (Turgot,  Reflexions,  &c.,  Oeuvres  ed.  Dairet.  I.  p.  10).  "  The  price 
of  the  necessaries  of  life  is,  in  fact,  the  cost  of  producing  labour,"  (Malthus, 
Inquiry  into,  &c.,  Rent,  London,  1815,  p.  48  note). 


The  Concept  of  Relative  Surplus-  Value.       303 

originate  in  the  curtailment  of  the  necessary  labour- time  ;  the 
latter  cannot  arise  from  the  former.  In  the  example  we  have 
taken,  it  is  necessary  that  the  value  of  labour-power  should 
actually  fall  by  one-tenth,  in  order  that  the  necessary  labour- 
time  may  be  diminished  by  one-tenth,  i.e.^  from  ten  hours  to 
nine,  and  in  order  that  the  surplus-labour  may  consequently 
be  prolonged  from  two  hours  to  three. 

Such  a  fall  in  the  value  of  labour-power  implies,  however, 
that  the  same  necessaries  of  life  which  were  formerly  produced 
in  ten  hours,  can  now  be  produced  in  nine  hours.  But  this  is 
impossible  without  an  increase  in  the  productiveness  of  labour. ' 
For  example,  suppose  a  shoemaker,  with  given  tools,  makes  in 
one  working  day  of  twelve  hours,  one  pair  of  boots.  If  he 
must  make  two  pairs  in  the  same  time,  the  productiveness  of 
his  labour  must  be  doubled ;  and  this  cannot  be  done,  except 
by  an  alteration  in  his  tools  or  in  his  mode  of  working,  or  in 
both.  Hence,  the  conditions  of  production,  i.e.,  his  mode  of 
production,  and  the  labour-process  itself,  must  be  revolu- 
tionised. By  increase  in  the  productiveness  of  labour,  we 
mean,  generally,  an  alteration  in  the  labour-process,  of  such  a 
kind  as  to  shorten  the  labour- time  socially  necessary  for  the 
production  of  a  commodity,  and  to  endow  a  given  quantity  of 
labour  with  the  power  of  producing  a  greater  quantity  of  use- 
value.^  Hitherto  in  treating  of  surplus-value,  arising  from  a 
simple  prolongation  of  the  working  day,  we  have  assumed  the 
mode  of  production  to  be  given  and  invariable.  But  when 
surplus-value  has  to  be  produced  by  the  conversion  of  necessary 
labour  into  surplus-labour,  it  by  no  means  suffices  for  capital 
to  take  over  the  labour-process  in  the  form  under  which  it  has 
been  historically  handed  down,  and  then  simply  to  prolong  the 
duration  of  that  process.  The  technical  and  social  conditions 
of  the  process,  and  consequently  the  very  mode  of  production 
must  be  revolutionised,  before  the  productiveness  of  labour  can 
be  increased.     By  that  means  alone  can  the  value  of  labour- 

1  "Quando  si  perfezionano  le  arti,  chenon  d  altro  che  la  scoperta  dinuove  vie,  onde 
si  possa  compiere  una  manufattura  con  meno  gente  o  (che  e  lo  stesso)  in  minor  tempo 
di  prima."  (Galiani  1.  c.  p.  159.)  "L'economie  sur  les  frais  de  production  ne  peu 
done  6tre  autre  chose  que  I'ficonomie  sur  la  quantity  de  travail  employe  pour 
produire."    (Sismondi  Etudes  t.  I.  p.  22.) 


304  Capitalist  Production. 

power  be  made  to  sink,  and  the  portion  of  the  working  day 
necessary  for  the  reproduction  of  that  value,  be  shortened. 

The  surplus-value  produced  by  prolongation  of  the  working 
day,  I  call  absolute  surplus-value.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
surplus-value  arising  from  the  curtailment  of  the  necessary 
labour-time,  and  from  the  corresponding  alteration  in  the  re- 
spective lengths  of  the  two  components  of  the  working  day,  I 
call  relative  surplus-value. 

In  order  to  effect  a  fall  in  the  value  of  labour-power,  the  in- 
crease in  the  productiveness  of  labour  must  seize  upon  those 
branches  of  industry,  whose  products  determine  the  value  of 
labour-power,  and  consequently  either  belong  to  the  class  of 
customary  means  of  subsistence,  or  are  capable  of  supplying 
the  place  of  those  means.  But  the  value  of  a  commodity  is  de- 
termined, not  only  by  the  quantity  of  labour  which  the 
labourer  directly  bestows  upon  that  commodity,  but  also  by  the 
labour  contained  in  the  means  of  production.  For  instance, 
the  value  of  a  pair  of  boots  depends,  not  only  on  the  cobbler's 
labour,  but  also  on  the  value  of  the  leather,  wax,  thread,  &c. 
Hence,  a  fall  in  the  value  of  labour-power  is  also  brought  about 
by  an  increase  in  the  productiveness  of  labour,  and  by  a  corres- 
ponding cheapening  of  commodities  in  those  industries  which 
supply  the  instruments  of  labour  and  the  raw  material,  that 
form  the  material  elements  of  the  constant  capital  required  for 
producing  the  necessaries  of  life.  But  an  increase  in  the  pro- 
ductiveness of  labour  in  those  branches  of  industry  which 
supply  neither  the  necessaries  of  life,  nor  the  means  of  produc- 
tion for  such  necessaries,  leaves  the  value  of  labour-power  un- 
disturbed. 

The  cheapened  commodity,  of  course,  causes  only  a  pro 
tanto  fall  in  the  value  of  labour-power,  a  fall  proportional  to 
the  extent  of  that  commodity's  employment  in  the  reproduc- 
tion of  labour-power.  Shirts,  for  instance,  are  a  necessary 
means  of  subsistence,  but  are  only  one  out  of  many.  The 
totality  of  the  necessaries  of  life  consists,  however,  of  various 
commodities,  each  the  product  of  a  distinct  industry ;  and  the 
value  of  each  of  those  commodities  enters  as  a  component  part 
into  the  value  of  labour-power.     This  latter  value  decreases 


The  Concept  of  Relative  Surplus-  Vahce,      305 

with  the  decrease  of  the  labour-time  necessary  for  its  reproduc- 
tion ;  the  total  decrease  being  the  sum  of  all  the  different  cur- 
tailments of  labour-time  effected  in  those  various  and  distinct 
industries.  This  general  result  is  treated,  here,  as  if  it  were 
the  immediate  result  directly  aimed  at  in  each  individual  case. 
Whenever  an  individual  capitalist  cheapens  shirts,  for  instance, 
by  increasing  the  productiveness  of  labour,  he  by  no  means 
necessarily  aims  at  reducing  the  value  of  labour-power  and 
shortening,  pro  tanto,  the  necessary  labour-time.  But  it  is  only 
in  so  far  as  he  ultimately  contributes  to  this  result,  that  he 
assists  in  raising  the  general  rate  of  surplus-value.^  The 
general  and  necessary  tendencies  of  capital  must  be  distin- 
guished from  their  forms  of  manifestation. 

It  is  not  our  intention  to  consider,  here,  the  way  in  which 
the  laws,  immanent  in  capitalist  production,  manifest  them- 
selves in  the  movements  of  individual  masses  of  capital,  where 
they  assert  themselves  as  coercive  laws  of  competition,  and  are 
brought  home  to  the  mind  and  consciousness  of  the  individual 
capitalist  as  the  directing  motives  of  his  operations.  But  this 
much  is  clear ;  a  scientific  analysis  of  competition  is  not 
possible,  before  we  have  a  conception  of  the  inner  nature  of 
capital,  just  as  the  apparent  motions  of  the  heavenly  bodies 
are  not  intelligible  to  any  but  him,  who  is  acquainted  with 
their  real  motions,  motions  which  are  not  directly  perceptible 
by  the  senses.  Nevertheless,  for  the  better  comprehension  of 
the  production  of  relative  surplus-value,  we  may  add  the 
following  remarks,  in  which  we  assume  nothing  more  than  the 
results  we  have  already  obtained. 

If  one  hour's  labour  is  embodied  in  sixpence,  a  value  of  six 
shillings  will  be  produced  in  a  working  day  of  12  hours. 
Suppose,  that  with  the  prevailing  productiveness  of  labour,  12 
articles  are  produced  in  these  12  hours.  Let  the  value  of  the 
means  of  production  used  up  in  each  article  be  sixpence.  Under 
these  circumstances,  each  article  costs  one  shilling :  sixpence 
for  the  value  of  the  means  of  production,  and  sixpence  for  the 

1  "  Let  us  suppose the  products ....  of  the  manufacturer  are  doubled  by 

improvement  in  machinery  ...  he  will  be  able  to  clothe  his  workmen  by  means  of 
a  smaller  proportion  of  the  entire  return  .  .  .  and  thus  his  profit  will  be  raised. 
But  in  no  other  way  will  it  be  influenced."    (Ramsay,  1.  c.  p.  168,  169.) 

U 


3o6  Capitalist  Production. 

value  newly  added  in  working  with  those  means.  Now  let 
some  one  capitalist  contrive  to  double  the  productiveness  of 
labour,  and  to  produce  in  the  working  day  of  12  hours,  24  in- 
stead of  12  such  articles.  The  value  of  the  means  of  produc- 
tion remaining  the  same,  the  value  of  each  article  will  fall  to 
niiiepence,  made  up  of  sixpence  for  the  value  of  the  means  of 
production  and  threepence  for  the  value  newly  added  by  the 
labour.  Despite  the  doubled  productiveness  of  labour,  the 
day's  labour  creates,  as  before,  a  new  value  of  six  shillings  and 
no  more,  which,  however,  is  now  spread  over  twice  as  many 
articles.  Of  this  value  each  article  now  has  embodied  in  it  ^V^h, 
instead  of  y^th,  threepence  instead  of  sixpence ;  or,  what 
amounts  to  the  same  thing,  only  half  an  hour's  instead  of  a 
whole  hour's  labour-time,  is  now  added  to  the  means  of  pro- 
duction while  they  are  being  transformed  into  each  article. 
The  individual  value  of  these  articles  is  now  below  their  social 
value ;  in  other  words,  they  have  cost  less  labour-time  than 
the  great  bulk  of  the  same  article  produced  under  the  average 
social  conditions.  Each  article  costs,  on  an  average,  one  shilling, 
and  represents  2  hours  of  social  labour ;  but  under  the  altered 
mode  of  production  it  costs  only  ninepence,  or  contains  only  1 J 
hours'  labour.  The  real  value  of  a  commodity  is,  however,  not 
its  individual  value,  but  its  social  value ;  that  is  to  say,  the 
real  value  is  not  measured  by  the  labour-time  that  the  article 
in  each  individual  case  costs  the  producer,  but  by  the  labour- 
time  socially  required  for  its  production.  If  therefore,  the 
capitalist  who  applies  the  new  method,  sells  his  commodity 
at  its  social  value  of  one  shilling,  he  sells  it  for  threepence 
above  its  individual  value,  and  thus  realises  an  extra  surplus- 
value  of  threepence.  On  the  other  hand,  the  working  day  of 
12  hours  is,  as  regards  him,  now  represented  by  24  articles 
instead  of  12.  Hence,  in  order  to  get  rid  of  the  product  of 
one  working  day,  the  demand  must  be  double  what  it  was,  i.e., 
the  market  must  become  twice  as  extensive.  Other  thinofs 
being  equal,  his  commodities  can  command  a  more  extended 
market  only  by  a  diminution  of  their  prices.  He  will  there- 
fore sell  them  above  their  individual  but  under  their  social 
value,  say  at  tenpence  each.     Bj^  this  means  he  still  squeezes 


The  Concept  of  Relative  Siirplus-  Value,       307 

an  extra  surplus-value  of  one  penny  out  of  each.  This  aug- 
mentation of  surplus-value  is  pocketed  by  him,  whether  his 
commodities  belong  or  not  to  the  class  of  necessary  means  of 
subsistence  that  participate  in  determining  the  general  value  of 
labour-power.  Hence, independently  of  this  latter  circumstance, 
there  is  a  motive  for  each  individual  capitalist  to  cheapen 
his  commodities,  by  increasing  the  productiveness  of  labour. 

Nevertheless,  even  in  this  case,  the  increased  production  of 
surplus-value  arises  from  the  curtailment  of  the  necessary 
labour-time,  and  from  the  corresponding  prolongation  of  the 
surplus-labour.^  Let  the  necessary  labour-time  amount  to 
10  hours,  the  value  of  a  day's  labour- power  to  five  shillings,  the 
surplus  labour-time  to  2  hours,  and  the  daily  surplus- value  to 
one  shilling.  But  the  capitalist  now  produces  24  articles, 
which  he  sells  at  tenpence  a-piece,  making  twenty  shillings  in 
all.  Since  the  value  of  the  means  of  production  is  twelve 
shillings,  14|  of  these  articles  merely  replace  the  constant 
capital  advanced.  The  labour  of  the  12  hours'  working  day  is 
represented  by  the  remaining  9f  articles.  Since  the  price  of 
the  labour-power  is  five  shillings,  6  articles  represent  the 
necessary  labour-time,  and  3f  articles  the  surplus-labour.  The 
ratio  of  the  necessary  labour  to  the  surplus-labour,  which  under 
average  social  conditions  was  5  :  1,  is  now  only  5  :  3.  The 
same  result  may  be  arrived  at  in  the  following  way.  The 
value  of  the  product  of  the  working  day  of  12  hours  is  twenty 
shillings.  Of  this  sum,  twelve  shillings  belong  to  the  value  of 
the  means  of  production,  a  value  that  merely  re-appears. 
There  remain  eight  shillings,  which  are  the  expression  in 
money,  of  the  value  newly  created  during  the  working  day. 
This  sum  is  greater  than  the  sum  in  which  average  social 
labour  of  the  same  kind  is  expressed  :  twelve  hours  of  the 
latter  labour  are  expressed  by  six  shillings  only.  The  excep- 
tionally productive  labour  operates  as  intensified  labour;    it 

1  "  A  man's  profit  does  not  depend  upon  his  command  of  the  produce  of  other  men's 
labour,  but  upon  his  command  of  labour  itself.  If  he  can  sell  his  goods  at  a  higher 
price,  while  his  workmen's  wages  remain  unaltered,  he  is  clearly  benefited.  ...  A 
smaller  proportion  of  what  he  produces  is  sufficient  to  put  that  labour  into  motion, 
and  a  larger  proportion  consequently  remains  for  himself."  (' '  Outlines  of  Pol.  Econ." 
London,  1832,  pp.  49,  50.) 


3o8  Capitalist  Production. 

creates  in  equal  periods  of  time  greater  values  than  average 
social  labour  of  the  same  kind.  (See  Ch.  I.  Sect.  1.  p.  11.)  But 
our  capitalist  still  continues  to  pay  as  before  only  five  shillings 
as  the  value  of  a  day's  labour-power.  Hence,  instead  of  10 
hours,  the  labourer  need  now  work  only  7i  hours,  in  order  to 
re-produce  this  value.  His  surplus-labour  is,  therefore,  in- 
creased by  24  hours,  and  the  surplus- value  he  produces  grows 
from  one,  into  three  shillings.  Hence,  the  capitalist  who 
applies  the  improved  method  of  production,  appropriates  to 
surplus-labour  a  greater  portion  of  the  working  day,  than  the 
other  capitalists  in  the  same  trade.  He  does  individually, 
what  the  whole  body  of  capitalists  engaged  in  producing  re- 
lative surplus-value,  do  collectively.  On  the  other  hand, 
however,  this  extra  surpluf^-value  vanishes,  so  soon  as  the  new 
method  of  production  has  become  general,  and  has  consequently 
caused  the  difference  between  the  individual  value  of  the 
cheapened  commodity  and  its  social  value  to  vanish.  The  law 
of  the  determination  of  value  by  labour-time,  a  law  which 
brings  under  its  sway  the  individual  capitalist  who  applies 
the  new  method  of  production,  by  compelling  him  to  sell  his 
goods  under  their  social  value,  this  same  law,  acting  as  a  co- 
ercive law  of  competition,  forces  his  competitors  to  adopt  the 
new  method.^  The  general  rate  of  surplus-value  is,  therefore, 
ultimately  affected  by  the  whole  process,  only  when  the  in- 
crease in  the  productiveness  of  labour,  has  seized  upon  those 
branches  of  production  that  are  connected  with,  and  has 
cheapened  those  commodities  that  form  part  of,  the  necessary 
means  of  subsistence,  and  are  therefore  elements  of  the  value 
of  labour-power. 

The  value  of  commodities  is  in  inverse  ratio  to  the  produc- 
tiveness of  labour.  And  so,  too,  is  the  value  of  labour-power, 
because   it  depends  on  the  values  of  commodities.     Relative 

1  "  If  my  neighbour  by  doing  much  with  little  labour,  can  sell  cheap,  I  must  con- 
trive to  sell  as  clieap  as  he.  So  that  every  art,  trade,  or  engine,  doing  work  with 
labour  of  fewer  hands,  and  consequently  cheaper,  begets  in  others  a  kind  of  necessity 
and  emulation,  either  of  using  the  same  art,  trade,  or  engine,  or  of  inventing  some 
thing  like  it,  that  every  man  may  be  upon  the  square,  that  no  man  may  be  able  to 
undersell  his  neighbour."  ("The  Advantages  of  the  East  India  Trade  to  England.'' 
London,  1720,  p.  67.) 


The  Concept  of  Relative  Surplus-  Value.       309 

surplus- value  is,  on  the  contrary,  directly  proportional  to  that 
productiveness.  It  rises  with  rising  and  falls  with  falling 
productiveness.  The  value  of  money  being  assumed  to  be 
constant,  an  average  social  working  day  of  12  hours  always 
produces  the  same  new  value,  six  shillings,  no  matter  how  this 
sum  ma}"  be  apportioned  between  surplus-value  and  wages. 
But  if,  in  consequence  of  increased  productiveness,  the  value 
of  the  necessaries  of  life  fall,  and  the  value  of  a  day's  labour- 
power  be  thereby  reduced  from  five  shillings  to  three,  the  sur  - 
plus-value  increases  from  one  shilling  to  three.  Ten  hours 
were  necessary  for  the  reproduction  of  the  value  of  the  labour- 
power  ;  now  only  six  are  required.  Four  hours  have  been  set 
free,  and  can  be  annexed  to  the  domain  of  surplus-labour. 
Hence  there  is  immanent  in  capital  an  inclination  and  constant 
tendency,  to  heighten  the  productiveness  of  labour,  in  order  to 
cheapen  commodities,  and  by  such  cheapening  to  cheapen  the 
labourer  himself^ 

The  value  of  a  commodity  is,  in  itself,  of  no  interest  to  the 
.  capitalist.     What  alone  interests  him,  is  the,  ourplus-value  that 
/  dwells  in  it,  and  is  realisable  by  sale.     Realisation  of  the  sur- 
•   plus- value  necessarily  carries  with  it  the  refunding  of  the  value 
that   was   advanced.      Now,  since  relative   surplus- value  in- 
creases in  direct  proportion  to  the  development  of  the  produc- 
tiveness of  labour,  while,  on  the  other  hand,  the  value  of  com- 
modities diminishes  in  the  same  proportion ;  since  one  and  the 
same  process  cheapens  commodities,  and  augments  the  surplus- 
value  contained  in  them ;  we  have  here  the  solution  of  the 
riddle:  why  does  the  capitalist,  whose  sole  concern  is  the  pro- 
duction of  exchange- value,  continually  strive  to  depress  the 
exchange-value  of  commodities  ?    A  riddle  with  which  Quesnay, 

1  **  In  whatever  proportion  the  expenses  of  a  labourer  are  diminished,  in  the  same 
proportion  will  his  wages  be  diminished,  if  the  restraints  upon  industry  are  at  the 
same  time  taken  off."  ("  Considerations  concerning  taking  off  the  Bounty  on  Corn  Ex- 
ported," &c.,  Lond.,  1753,  p.  7.)  "  The  interest  of  trade  requires,  that  corn  and  all 
provisions  should  be  as  cheap  as  possible ;  for  whatever  makes  them  dear,  must  make 
labour  dear  also  ...  in  all  countries,  where  industry  is  not  restrained,  the  price  of 
provisions  must  affect  the  price  of  labour.  This  will  always  be  diminished  when  the 
necessaries  of  life  grow  cheaper. "  (1.  c.  p.  3.)  "Wages  are  decreased  in  the  same 
proportion  as  the  powers  of  production  increase.  Machinery,  it  is  true,  cheapens  the 
necessaries  of  life,  but  it  also  cheapens  the  labourer."  ("A  Prize  Essay  on  the 
Comparative  Merits  of  Competition  and  Co-operation."    London,  1834,  p.  27.) 


310  Capitalist  Production. 

one  of  the  founders  of  political  economy,  tormented  his 
opponents,  and  to  which  they  could  give  him  no  answer. 
"  You  acknowledge,"  he  says,  "that  the  more  expenses  and  the 
cost  of  labour  can,  in  the  manufacture  of  industrial  products, 
be  reduced  without  injury  to  production,  the  more  advantage- 
ous is  such  reduction,  because  it  diminishes  the  price  of  the 
finished  article.  And  yet.  you  believe  that  the  production  of 
wealth,  wliich  arises  from  the  labour  of  the  workpeople,  con- 
sists   in   the   aucrmentabion   of  the   exchanoe-value   of  their 

o  o 

products."^ 

The  shortening  of  the  working  day  is,  therefore,  by  no 
means  what  is  aimed  at,  in  capitalist  production,  when  labour 
is  economised  by  increasing  its  productiveness.^  It  is  only  the 
shortening  of  the  labour-time,  necessary  for  the  production  of 
a  definite  quantity  of  commodities,  that  is  aimed  at.  The  fact 
that  the  workman,  when  the  productiveness  of  his  labour  has 
been  increased,  produces,  say  10  times  as  many  commodities  as 
before,  and  thus  spends  one-tenth  as  much  labour-time  on  each, 
by  no  means  prevents  him  from  continuing  to  work  12  hours  as 
lefore,  nor  from  producing  in  those  12  hours  1200  articles  in- 
stead of  120.  Nay,  more,  his  working  day  may  be  prolonged 
at  the  same  time,  so  as  to  make  him  produce,  say  1400  articles 
in  14  hours.  In  the  treatises,  therefore,  of  economists  of  the 
stamp  of  MacCulloch,  Ure,  Senior,  and  tutti  quanti,  we  may 
read  upon  one  page,  that  the  labourer  owes  a  debt  of  gratitude 
to  capital  for  developing  his  productiveness,  because  the 
necessary  labour-time  is  thereby  shortened,  and  on  the  next 
page,  that  he  must  prove  his  gratitude  by  working  in  future 

^  "  lis  conviennent  que  plus  on  peut,  sans  prejudice,  epargner  de  frais  ou  de  travaux 
dispendieux  dans  la  fabrication  des  ouvrages  des  artisans,  plus  cette  epargne  est  pro- 
fitable par  la  diminution  des  prix  de  ces  ouvrages.  Cependant  ils  croient  que  la  pro- 
duction de  richesse  qui  resulte  des  travaux  des  artisans  consiste  dans  I'augmentation 
de  la  valeur  venale  de  leurs  ouvrages. "  (Quesnay :  ' '  Dialogues  sur  le  Commerce  et  sur 
leg  Travaux  des  artisans,"  pp.  188, 189.) 

2  "  Ces  speculateurs  si  economes  du  travail  des  ouvriers  qu'il  faudrait  qu'ils  pay- 
assent."  (J.  N.  Bidaut :  *'Du  Monopole  qui  s'6tablit  dans  les  arts  industriels  et  le 
commerce."  Paris,  1828,  p.  13.)  "The  employer  will  be  always  on  the  stretch  to 
economise  time  and  labour.'*  (Dugald  Stewart:  Works  ed.  by  Sir  W.  Hainilton. 
Edinburgh,  v.  viii.,  1855.  Lectures  on  Polit.  Econ.,  p.  318.)  "Their  (the  capitalists') 
interest  is  that  the  productive  powers  of  the  labourers  they  employ  should  be  the 
greatest  possible.  On  promoting  that  power  their  attention  is  fixed  and  almost  ex- 
clusively fixed."    (R.  Jones  :  1   o   Lecture  III.) 


Co-  Operation.  311 

for  15  hours  instead  of  10.  The  object  of  all  development  of 
the  productiveness  of  labour,  within  the  limits  of  capitalist 
production,  is  to  shorten  that  part  of  the  working  day,  during 
which  the  workman  must  labour  for  his  own  benefit,  and  by 
that  very  shortening,  to  lengthen  the  other  part  of  the  day, 
during  which  he  is  at  liberty  to  work  gratis  for  the  capitalist. 
How  far  this  result  is  also  attainable,  without  cheapening 
commodities,  will  appear  from  an  examination  of  the  particular 
modes  of  producing  relative  surplus-value,  to  which  examina- 
tion we  now  proceed. 


CHAPTER  XIII. 

CO-OPERATION. 


Capitalist  production  only  then  really  begins,  as  we  have 
already  seen,  when  each  individual  capital  employs  simultane- 
ously a  comparatively  large  number  of  labourers  ;  when  conse- 
quently the  labour-process  is  carried  on  on  an  extensive  scale 
and  yields,  relatively,  large  quantities  of  products.  A  greater 
number  of  labourers  working:  too^ether,  at  the  same  time,  in 
one  place  (or,  if  you  will,  in  the  same  field  of  labour),  in  order 
to  produce  the  same  sort  of  commodity  under  the  mastership 
of  one  capitalist,  constitutes,  both  historically  and  logically, 
the  starting  point  of  capitalist  production.  With  regard  to 
the  mode  of  production  itself,  manufacture,  in  its  strict  mean- 
ing, is  hardly  to  be  distinguished,  in  its  earliest  stages,  from 
the  handicraft  trades  of  the  guilds,  otherwise  than  by  the 
greater  number  of  workmen  simultaneously  employed  by  one 
and  the  same  individual  capital.  The  workshop  of  the 
mediaeval  master  handicraftsman  is  simply  enlarged. 

At  first,  therefore,  the  difference  is  purely  quantitative.  We 
have  shown  that  the  surplus-value  produced  by  a  given  capital 
is  equal  to  the  surplus-value  produced  by  each  workman  mul- 
tiplied by  the  number  of  workmen  simultaneously  employed. 
The  number  of  workmen  in  itself  does  not  affect,  either  the  rate 
of  surplus- value,  or  the  degree  of  exploitation  of  labour-power. 
If  a  working  day  of  12  hours  be  embodied  in  six  shillings,  1200 


312  Capitalist  Production 

such  days  will  be  embodied  in  1200  times  6  shillings.  In  one 
case  12  X  1200  working  hours,  and  in  the  other  12  such  hours 
are  incorporated  in  the  product.  In  the  production  of  value 
a  number  of  workmen  rank  merely  as  so  many  individual 
workmen ;  and  it  therefore  makes  no  difference  in  the  value 
produced  whether  the  1200  men  work  separately,  or  united 
under  the  control  of  one  capitalist 

Nevertheless,  within  certain  limits,  a  modification  takes 
place.  The  labour  realised  in  value,  is  labour  of  an  average 
social  quality  ;  is  consequently  the  expenditure  of  average 
labour-power.  Any  average  magnitude,  however,  is  merely 
the  average  of  a  number  of  separate  magnitudes  all  of  one 
kind,  but  differing  as  to  quantity.  In  every  industry,  each 
individual  labourer,  be  he  Peter  or  Paul,  differs  from  the 
average  labourer.  These  individual  differences,  or  "  errors  " 
as  they  are  called  in  mathematics,  compensate  one  another, 
and  vanish,  whenever  a  certain  minimum  number  of  workmen 
are  employed  together.  The  celebrated  sophist  and  sycophant, 
Edmund  Burke,  goes  so  far  as  to  make  the  following  assertion, 
based  on  his  practical  observations  as  a  farmer  ;  viz.,  that  "  in 
so  small  a  platoon  "  as  that  of  ^w^  farm  labourers,  all  indi- 
vidual differences  in  the  labour  vanish,  and  that  consequently 
any  given  five  adult  farm  labourers  taken  together,  will  in  the 
same  time  do  as  much  work  as  any  other  five.^  But,  however 
that  may  be,  it  is  clear,  that  the  collective  working  day  of  a 
large  number  of  Workmen  simultaneously  employed,  divided 
by  the  number  of  these  workmen,  gives  one  day  of  average 
social  labour.  For  example,  let  the  working  day  of  each 
individual  be  12  hours.  Then  the  collective  working  day  of 
12  men  simultaneously  employed,  consists  of  144  hours;  and 
although  the  labour  of  each  of  the  dozen  men  may  deviate 

"^  "Unquestionably,  there  is  a  good  deal  of  difference  between  the  value  of  one 
man's  labour  and  that  of  another  from  strength,  dexterity,  and  honest  application. 
But  I  am  quite  sure,  from  my  best  observation,  that  any  given  five  men  will,  in  their 
total,  afford  a  proportion  of  labour  equal  to  any  other  five  within  the  periods  of  life  I 
have  stated  ;  that  is,  that  among  such  five  men  there  will  be  one  possessing  all  the 
qualifications  of  a  good  workman,  one  bad,  and  the  other  three  middling,  and  ap- 
proximating to  the  first  and  the  last.  So  that  in  so  small  a  platoon  as  that  of  even 
five,  you  will  find  the  full  complement  of  all  that  five  men  can  earn. "  (E.  Burke,  1. 
c.  p.  15,  16).    Compare  Quetelet  on  the  average  individual. 


Co-  Operation,  3 1 3 

more  or  less  from  average  social  labour,  each  of  them  requiring 
a  different  time  for  the  same  operation,  yet  since  the  work- 
ing day  of  each  is  one-twelfth  of  the  collective  working  day 
of  144«  hours,  it  possesses  the  qualities  of  an  average  social 
working  day.  From  the  point  of  view,  however,  of  the  capi- 
talist who  employs  these  12  men,  the  working  day  is  that  of 
the  whole  dozen.  Each  individual  man's  day  is  an  aliquot 
part  of  the  collective  working  day,  no  matter  whether  the  12 
men  assist  one  another  in  their  work,  or  whether  the  connexion 
between  their  operations  consists  merely  in  the  fact,  that  the 
men  are  all  working  for  the  same  capitalist.  But  if  the  1 2 
men  are  employed  in  six  pairs,  by  as  many  different  small 
masters,  it  will  be  quite  a  matter  of  chance,  whether  each  of 
these  masters  produces  the  same  value,  and  consequently 
whether  he  realises  the  general  rate  of  surplus-value.  Devia- 
tions would  occur  in  individual  cases.  If  one  workman  re- 
quired considerably  more  time  for  the  production  of  a  com- 
modity than  is  socially  necessary,  the  duration  of  the  necessary 
labour-time  would,  in  his  case,  sensibly  deviate  from  the 
labour- time  socially  necessary  on  an  average;  and  consequently 
his  labour  would  not  count  as  average  labour,  nor  his  labour- 
power  as  average  labour-power.  Ic  would  either  be  not  sale- 
able at  all,  or  only  at  something  below  the  average  value  of 
labour-power.  A  fixed  minimum  of  efficiency  in  all  labour  is 
therefore  assumed,  and  we  shall  see,  later  on,  that  capita- 
list production  provides  the  means  of  fixing  this  minimum. 
Nevertheless,  this  minimum  deviates  from  the  average,  al- 
though on  the  other  hand  the  capitalist  has  to  pay  the  average 
value  of  labour-power.  Of  the  six  small  masters,  one  would 
therefore  squeeze  out  more  than  the  average  rate  of  surplus- 
•value,  another  less.  The  inequalities  would  be  compensated 
for  the  society  at  large,  but  not  for  the  individual  masters. 
Thus  the  laws  of  the  production  of  value  are  only  fully  realised 
for  the  individual  producer,  when  he  produces  as  a  capitalist, 
and  employes  a  number  of  workmen  together,  whose  labour, 
by  its  collective  nature,  is  at  once  stamped  as  average  social 
labour.^ 

'  Professor  Roscher  claims  to  have  discovered  that  one  needlewoman  employed  by 


314  Capitalist  Production. 

Even  without  an  alteration  in  the  system  of  working,  the 
simultaneous  employment  of  a  large  number  of  labourers 
effects  a  revolution  in  the  material  conditions  of  the  labour- 
process.  The  buildings  in  which  they  work,  the  store-houses 
for  the  raw  material,  the  implements  and  utensils  used  simul- 
taneously or  in  turns  by  the  workmen ;  in  short,  a  portion  of 
the  means  of  production,  are  now  consumed  in  common.  On 
the  one  hand,  the  exchange-value  of  these  means  of  production 
is  not  increased  ;  for  the  exchange-value  of  a  commodity  is  not 
raised  by  its  use- value  being  consumed  more  thoroughly  and  to 
greater  advantage.  On  the  other  hand,  they  are  used  in  com- 
mon, and  therefore  on  a  larger  scale  than  before.  A  room 
where  twenty  weavers  work  at  twenty  looms  must  be  larger 
than  the  room  of  a  sincrle  weaver  with  two  assistants.  But  it 
costs  less  labour  to  build  one  workshop  for  twenty  persons 
than  to  build  ten  to  accommodate  two  weavers  each  ;  thus 
the  value  of  the  means  of  production  that  are  concentrated  for 
use  in  common  on  a  large  scale  does  not  increase  in  direct  pro- 
portion to  the  expansion  and  to  the  increased  useful  effect  of 
those  means.  When  consumed  in  common,  they  give  up  a 
smaller  part  of  their  value  to  each  single  product ;  partly 
because  the  total  value  they  part  with  is  spread  over  a  greater 
quantity  of  products,  and  partly  because  their  value,  though 
absolutely  greater,  is,  having  regard  to  their  sphere  of  action  in 
the  process,  relatively  less  than  the  value  of  isolated  means  of 
production.  Owing  to  this,  the  value  of  a  part  of  the  constant 
capital  falls,  and  in  proportion  to  the  magnitude  of  the  fall,  the 
total  value  of  the  commodity  also  falls.  The  effect  is  the  same 
as  if  the  means  of  production  had  cost  less.  The  economy 
in  their  application  is  entirely  owing  to  their  being  con- 
sumed in  common  by  a  large  number  of  workmen.  Moreover, 
this  character  of  being  necessary  conditions  of  social  labour,  a 
character  that  distinguishes  them  from  the  dispersed  and 
relatively  more  costly  means  of  production  of  isolated,  inde- 
pendent labourers,  or  small  masters,  is  acquired  even  when  the 

Mrs.  Roscher  during  two  days,  does  more  work  than  two  needlewomen  employed 
together  during  one  day.  The  learned  professor  should  not  study  the  capitalist  pro- 
cess of  production  in  the  nursery,  nor  under  circumstances  where  the  principal  per- 
sonage, the  capitalist,  is  wanting. 


Co-Operation,  315 

numerous  workmen  assembled  togetlier  do  not  assist  one 
another,  but  merely  work  side  by  side.  A  portion  of  the 
instruments  of  labour  acquires  this  social  character  before  the 
labour-process  itself  does  so. 

Economy  in  the  use  of  the  means  of  production  has  to  be 
considered  under  two  aspects.  First,  as  cheapening  commodi- 
ties, and  thereby  bringing  about  a  fall  in  the  value  of  labour- 
power.  Secondly,  as  altering  the  ratio  of  the  surplus-value  to 
the  total  capital  advanced,  i.e.,  to  the  sum  of  the  values  of  the 
constant  and  variable  capital.  The  latter  aspect  will  not  be 
considered  until  we  come  to  the  third  book,  to  which,  with  the 
object  of  treating  them  in  their  proper  connexion,  we  also 
relegate  many  other  points  that  relate  to  the  present  question. 
The  march  of  our  analysis  compels  this  splitting  up  of  the 
subject  matter,  a  splitting  up  that  is  quite  in  keeping  with  the 
spirit  of  capitalist  production.  For  since,  in  this  mode  of  pro- 
duction, the  workman  finds  the  instruments  of  labour  exivsting 
independently  of  him  as  another  man's  property,  economy  in 
their  use  appears,  with  regard  to  him,  to  be  a  distinct  operation, 
one  that  does  not  concern  him,  and  which,  therefore,  has  no 
connextion  with  the  methods  by  which  his  own  personal  pro- 
ductiveness is  increased. 

When  numerous  labourers  work  together  side  by  side, 
whether  in  one  and  the  same  process,  or  in  different  but  con- 
nected processes,  they  are  said  to  co-operate,  or  to  work  in  co- 
operation.^ 

Just  as  the  offensive  power  of  a  squadron  of  cavalry,  or  the 
defensive  power  of  a  regiment  of  infantry,  is  essentially 
different  from  the  sum  of  the  offensive  or  defensive  powers  of 
the  individual  cavalry  or  infantry  soldiers  taken  separately,  so 
the  sum  total  of  the  mechanical  forces  exerted  by  isolated 
workmen  differs  from  the  social  force  that  is  developed,  when 
many  hands  take  part  simultaneously  in  one  and  the  same  un- 
divided operation,  such  as  raising  a  heavy  weight,  turning  a 
winch,  or  removing  an  obstacle.^     In  such  cases  the  effect  of 

1  **  Concourn  de  forces."    (Destutt  de  Tracy,  1.  c,  p.  78.) 

2  "  There  are  numerous  operations  of  so  simple  a  kind  as  not  to  admit  a  division 
into  parts,  which  cannot  be  performed  without  the  co-operation  of  many  pairs  of 
hands.     I  would  instance  the  lifting  of  a  large  tree  on  to  a  wain.  .  .  .  everything,  iu 


3i6  Capitalist  Production, 

the  combined  labour  could  either  not  be  produced  at  all  by 
isolated  individual  labour,  or  it  could  only  be  produced  by  a 
great  expenditure  of  time,  or  on  a  very  dwarfed  scale.  Not 
only  have  we  here  an  increase  in  the  productive  power  of  the 
individual,  by  means  of  co-operation,  but  the  creation  of  a  new 
power,  namely,  the  collective  power  of  masses.^ 

-Apart  from  the  new  power  that  arises  from  the  fusion  of 
many  forces  into  one  single  force,  mere  social  contact  begets  in 
most  industries  an  emulation  and  a  stimulation  of  the  animal 
spirits  that  heighten  the  efficiency  of  each  individual  workman. 
Hence  it  is  that  a  dozen  persons  working  together  will,  in 
their  collective  working-day  of  144  hours,  produce  far  more 
than  twelve  isolated  men  each  working  12  hours,  or  than  one 
man  who  works  twelve  days  in  succession.^  The  reason  of 
this  is  that  man  is,  if  not  as  Aristotle  contends,  a  political,^  at 
all  events  a  social  animal. 

Although  a  number  of  men  may  be  occupied  together  at  the 
same  time  on  the  same,  or  the  same  kind  of  work,  yet  the 
labour  of  each,  as  a  part  of  the  collective  labour,  maj''  corres- 
pond to  a  distinct  phase  of  the  labour-process,  through  all  whose 
phases,  in  consequence  of  co-operation,  the  subject  of  their 
labour  passes  with  greater  speed.  For  instance,  if  a  dozen 
masons  place  themselves  in  a  row,  so  as  to  pass  stones  from  the 

short,  which  cannot  be  done  unless  a  great  many  pairs  of  hands  help  each  other  in 
the  same  undivided  employment  and  at  the  same  time  "  (E.  G.  Wakefield :  "A  View  of 
the  Art  of  Colonisation."    London  :  1849,  p.  168). 

1  "  As  one  man  cannot,  and  ten  men  must  strain  to  lift  a  tun  of  weight,  yet  100 
men  can  do  it  only  by  the  strength  of  a  finger  of  each  of  them. "  (John  Bellers  :  *'  Pro- 
posals for  raising  a  CoUedge  of  Industry."    London,  1696,  p.  21.) 

'^  "  There  is  also  "  (when  the  same  number  of  men  are  employed  by  one  farmer  on 
300  acres,  instead  of  by  ten  farmers  with  30  acres  a  piece)  ' '  an  advantage  in  the  pro- 
portion of  servants,  which  will  not  so  easily  be  understood  but  by  practical  men  ;  for  it 
is  natural  to  say,  as  1  is  to  4,  so  are  3  :  to  12  :  but  this  will  not  hold  good  in  practice ; 
for  in  harvest  time  and  many  other  operations  which  require  that  kind  of  despatch 
by  the  throwing  many  hands  together,  the  work  is  better  and  more  expeditiously 
done  :  f .  i.  in  harvest,  2  drivers,  2  loaders,  2  pitchers,  2  rakers,  and  the  rest  at  the 
rick,  or  in  the  barn,  will  despatch  double  the  work  that  the  same  number  of  hands 
would  do  if  divided  into  different  gangs  on  different  farms."  ("An  Inquiry  into  tlie 
connection  between  the  present  Price  of  Provisions  and  the  Size  of  Farms."  By  a 
Farmer.     London,  1773,  pp.  7,  8.) 

3  Strictly,  Aristotle's  definition  is  that  man  is  by  nature  a  town -citizen.  This  is 
quite  as  characteristic  of  ancient  classical  society  as  Franklin's  definition  of  man,  as 
a  tool-making  animal,  is  characteristic  of  Yankeedom. 


Co-  Operation.  3 1  *] 

foot  of  a  ladder  to  its  summit,  each  of  tliem  does  the  same 
thing  ;  nevertheless,  their  separate  acts  form  connected  parts  of 
one  total  operation ;  they  are  particular  phases,  which  must 
be  gone  through  by  each  stone  ;  and  the  stones  are  thus 
carried  up  quicker  by  the  24  hands  of  the  row  of  men  than 
they  could  be  if  each  man  went  separately  up  and  down  the 
ladder  with  his  burden.^  The  object  is  carried  over  the  same 
distance  in  a  shorter  time.  Again,  a  combination  of  labour 
occurs  whenever  a  building,  for  instance,  is  taken  in  hand  on 
different  sides  simultaneously ;  although  here  also  the  co- 
operating masons  are  doing  the  same,  or  the  same  kind  of 
work.  The  12  masons,  in  their  collective  working  day  of  144 
hours,  make  much  more  progress  with  the  building  than  one 
mason  could  make  working  for  12  days,  or  144  hours.  The 
reason  is,  that  a  body  of  men  working  in  concert  has  hands  and 
eyes  both  before  and  behind,  and  is,  to  a  certain  degree,  omni- 
present. The  various  parts  of  the  work  progress  simul- 
taneously. 

In  the  above  instances  we  have  laid  stress  upon  the  point 
that  the  men  do  the  same,  or  the  same  kind  of  work,  because 
this,  the  most  simple  form  of  labour  in  common,  plays  a  great 
part  in  co-operation,  even  in  its  most  fully  developed  stage. 
If  the  work  be  complicated,  then  the  mere  number  of  the  men 
who  co-operate  allows  of  the  various  operations  being  appor- 
tioned to  different  hands,  and,  consequently,  of  being  carried 
on  simultaneously.  The  time  necessary  for  the  completion  of 
the  whole  work  is  thereby  shortened.^ 

1  "  On  doit  encore  remarquer  que  cette  division  partielle  de  travail  pent  se  fairc 
quand  merae  les  ouvriers  sont  occupes  d'une  meme  besogne.  Des  masons  par  exemple, 
occupes  ^  faire  passer  de  mains  en  mains  des  briques  k  un  echafaudage  sui^erieur,  font 
tons  la  m^me  besogne,  et  pourtantil  existe  i>armi  eux  une  espece  de  division  de  travail, 
qui  consiste  en  ce  que  chaoun  d'eux  fait  passer  la  brique  par  un  espace  donne,  et  que 
tons  ensemble  la  font  parvenir  beaucoup  plus  promptement  k  I'endroit  marque  qu'ils 
ne  le  feraient  si  chaoun  d'eux  portait  sa  brique  s^parcment  jusqu  '^  I'echafaudago 
sup^rieur,"  (F.  Skarbek  :  "Theorie  des  richesses  sociales."  Paris,  1829.  t.  I. 
pp.  97,  98.) 

2  **  Est-il  question  d'executer  un  travail  complique,  plusieurs  choses  doivent  6tre 
faites  simultan^ment.  L'un  en  fait  une  pendant  que  I'autre  en  fait  une  autre,  et 
tous  contribuent  k  I'effet  qu'un  seal  homme  n'aurait  pu  produire.  L'un  rame  pendant 
que  I'autre  tient  le  gouvernail,  et  qu'un  troisieme  jette  le  filet  ou  harponne  le  poisson, 
et  la  p^che  a  uu  succes  impossible  sans  ce  concours."    (Destutt  de  Tracy,  1.  c.) 


3i8  Capitalist  Production, 

In  many  industries,  there  are  critical  periods,  determined  by 
the  nature  of  the  process,  during  which  certain  definite  results 
must  be  obtained.  For  instance,  if  a  flock  of  sheep  has  to  be 
shorn,  or  a  field  of  wheat  to  be  cut  and  harvested,  the  quantity 
and  quality  of  the  product  depends  on  the  work  being  begun 
and  ended  within  a  certain  time.  In  these  cases,  the  time 
that  ought  to  be  taken  by  the  process  is  prescribed,  just  as  it 
is  in  herring  fishing.  A  single  person  cannot  carve  a  working 
day  of  more  than,  say  12  hours,  out  of  the  natural  day,  but  100 
men  co-operating  extend  the  working  day  to  1,200  hours. 
The  shortness  of  the  time  allowed  for  the  work  is  compensated 
for  by  the  large  mass  of  labour  thrown  upon  the  field  of  pro- 
duction at  the  decisive  moment.  The  completion  of  the  task 
within  the  proper  time  depends  on  the  simultaneous  applica- 
tion of  numerous  combined  working  days  ;  the  amount  of  use- 
ful effect  depends  on  the  number  of  labourers ;  this  number, 
however,  is  always  smaller  than  the  number  of  isolated 
labourers  required  to  do  the  same  amount  of  work  in  the  same 
period.^  It  is  owing  to  the  absence  of  this  kind  of  co-opera- 
tion that,  in  the  western  part  of  the  United  States,  quantities 
of  corn,  and  in  those  parts  of  East  India  where  English  rule  has 
destroyed  the  old  communities,  quantities  of  cotton,  are  yearly 
wasted.2 

On  the  one  hand,  co-operation  allows  of  the  work  being 
carried  on  over  an  extended  space ;  it  is  consequently  impera- 
tively called  for  in  certain  undertakings,  such  as  draining,  con- 
structing dykes,  irrigation  works,  and  the  making  of  canals, 
roads  and  railways.     On  the  other  hand,  while  extending  the 

1  "The  doing  of  it  (agricultural  work)  at  the  critical  juncture  is  of  so  much  the 
greater  consequence."  ("An  Inquiry  into  the  Connection  between  the  Present  Price," 
&c.,  p.  9.)  "In  agriculture,  there  is  no  more  important  factor  than  that  of  time." 
(Liebig  :  "  Ueber  Theorie  und  Praxis  in  der  Landwirthschaft. "    1856.     p.  23.) 

2  "  The  next  evil  is  one  which  one  would  scarcely  expect  to  find  in  a  country  which 
exi)orts  more  labour  than  any  other  in  the  world,  with  the  exception,  perhaps,  of 
China  and  England — the  impossibility  of  procuring  a  sufficient  number  of  hands  to 
clean  the  cotton.  The  consequence  of  this  is  that  large  quantities  of  the  crop  are  left 
uni)icked,  while  another  portion  is  gathered  from  the  ground  when  it  has  fallen,  and 
is  of  course  discoloured  and  partially  rotted,  so  that  for  want  of  labour  at  the  proper 
season  the  cultivator  is  actually  forced  to  submit  to  the  loss  of  a  large  part  of  that 
crop  for  which  England  is  so  anxiously  looking."  (Bengal  Hurkaru.  Bi-Monthly 
Overland  Summary  of  News,  22nd  July,  18ul.) 


Co-  Operation.  319 

scale  of  production,  it  renders  possible  a  relative  contraction  of 
the  arena.  This  contraction  of  arena  simultaneous  with,  and 
arising  from,  extension  of  scale,  whereby  a  number  of  useless 
expenses  are  cut  down,  is  owing  to  the  conglomeration  of 
labourers,  to  the  aggregation  of  various  processes,  and  to  the 
concentration  of  the  means  of  production.^ 

The  combined  working  day  produces,  relatively  to  an  equal 
sum  of  isolated  working-days,  a  greater  quantity  of  use-values, 
and,  consequenth^,  diminishes  the  labour-time  necessary  for  the 
production  of  a  given  useful  effect.  Whether  the  combined 
working-day,  in  a  given  case,  acquires  this  increased  produc- 
tive power,  because  it  heightens  the  mechanical  force  of  labour, 
or  extends  its  sphere  of  action  over  a  greater  space,  or  con- 
tracts the  field  of  production  relatively  to  the  scale  of  produc- 
tion, or  at  the  critical  moment  sets  large  masses  of  labour  to 
work,  or  excites  emulation  between  individuals  and  raises  their 
animal  spirits,  or  impresses  on  the  similar  operations  carried  on 
by  a  number  of  men  the  stamp  of  continuity  and  many-sided- 
ness, or  performs  simultaneously  different  operations,  or  econo- 
mises the  means  of  production  by  use  in  common,  or  lends  to 
individual  labour  the  character  of  average  social  labour — which- 
ever of  these  be  the  cause  of  the  increase,  the  special  produc- 
tive power  of  the  combined  working  day  is,  under  all  circum- 
stances, the  social  productive  power  of  labour,  or  the  productive 
power  of  social  labour.  This  power  is  due  to  co-operation 
itself.  When  the  labourer  co-operates  systematically  with 
others,  he  strips  off  the  fetters  of  his  individuality,  and  de- 
velopes  the  capabilities  of  his  species.^ 

As  a  general  rule,  labourers  cannot  co-operate  without  being 
brought  together :  their  assemblage  in  one  place  is  a  necessary 

1  In  the  progress  of  culture  "all,  and  perhaps  more  than  all,  the  capital  and  labour 
which  once  loosely  occupied  500  acres,  are  now  concentrated  for  the  more  complete 
tillage  of  100."  Although  '*  relatively  to  the  amount  of  capital  and  labour  employed, 
space  is  concentrated,  it  is  an  enlarged  sphere  of  production,  as  compared  to  the 
sphere  of  i^roduction  formerly  occupied  or  worked  upon  by  one  single  independent 
agent  of  production."  (R.  Jones :  "An  Essay  on  the  Distribution  of  Wealth,"  part  I. 
On  Rent.     London,  1831,  p.  191.) 

2  '*  La  forza  di  ciascuno  uomo  e  m'uima,  ma  la  riunione  delle  minime  forze  forma 
una  forza  totale  maggiore  anche  della  somma  delle  forze  medesime  fino  a  die  le  forze 
per  essere  riunite  possono  dirainuere  il  tempo  ed  accrescerelo  sjmzio  della  loro  azione." 
(G.  R.  Carli,  Note  to  P.  Verri,  1.  c.  t.,  xv.  p.  196.) 


320  Capitalist  Prodtiction, 

condition  of  their  co-operation.  Hence  wage  labourers  cannot 
co-operate,  unless  they  are  employed  simultaneously  by  the 
same  capital,  the  same  capitalist,  and  unless  therefore  their 
labour-powers  are  bought  simultaneously  by  him.  The  total 
value  of  these  labour-powers,  or  the  amount  of  the  wages  of 
these  labourers  for  a  day,  or  a  week,  as  the  case  may  be,  must 
be  ready  in  the  pocket  of  the  capitalist,  before  the  workmen 
are  assembled  for  the  process  of  production.  The  payment  of 
300  workmen  at  once,  though  only  for  one  day,  requires  a 
greater  outlay  of  capital,  than  does  the  payment  of  a  smaller 
number  of  men,  week  by  week,  during  a  whole  year.  Hence 
the  number  of  the  labourers  that  co-operate,  or  the  scale  of 
co-operation,  depends,  in  the  first  instance,  on  the  amount  of 
capital  that  the  individual  capitalist  can  spare  for  the  purchase 
of  labour-power ;  in  other  words,  on  the  extent  to  which  a 
single  capitalist  has  command  over  the  means  of  subsistence  of 
a  number  of  labourers. 

And  as  with  the  variable,  so  it  is  with  the  constant  capital. 
For  example,  the  outlay  on  raw  material  is  30  times  as  great, 
for  the  capitalist  who  employs  300  men,  as  it  is  for  each  of 
the  30  capitalists  who  employ  10  men.  The  value  and  quan- 
tity of  the  instruments  of  labour  used  in  common  do  not,  it  is 
true,  increase  at  the  same  rate  as  the  number  of  workmen,  but 
they  do  increase  very  considerably.  Hence,  concentration  of 
large  masses  of  the  means  of  production  in  the  hands  of  indi- 
vidual capitalists,  is  a  material  condition  for  the  co-opej-ation 
of  wage-labourers,  and  the  extent  of  the  co-operation  or  the 
scale  of  production,  depends  on  the  extent  of  this  concentration. 

We  saw  in  a  former  chapter,  that  a  certain  minimum  amount 
of  capital  was  necessary,  in  order  that  the  number  of  labourers 
simultaneously  employed,  and,  consequently,  the  amount  of 
surplus-value  produced,  might  suffice  to  liberate  the  employer 
himself  from  manual  labour,  to  convert  him  from  a  small 
master  into  a  capitalist,  and  thus  formally  to  establish  capita- 
list production.  We  now  see  that  a  certain  minimum  amount 
is  a  necessary  condition  for  the  conversion  of  numerous  isolated 
and  independent  processes  into  one  combined  social  process. 

We  also  saw  that  at  first,  the  subjection  of  labour  to  capital 


\ 


Co-  Operation,  321 

was  only  a  formal  result  of  the  fact,  that  the  labourer,  instead 
of  working  for  himself,  works  for  and  consequently  under  the 
capitalist.  By  the  co-operation  of  numerous  wage- labourers, 
the  sway  of  capital  developes  into  a  requisite  for  carrying  on 
the  labour-process  itself,  into  a  real  requisite  of  production. 
That  a  capitalist  should  command  on  the  field  of  production, 
is  now  as  indispensable  as  that  a  general  should  command  on 
the  field  of  battle. 

All  combined  labour  on  a  large  scale  requires,  more  or  less,  a 
directing  authority,  in  order  to  secure  the  harmonious  working 
of  the  individual  activities,  and  to  perform  the  general  func- 
tions that  have  their  origin  in  the  action  of  the  combined 
organism,  as  distinguished  from  the  action  of  its  separate 
organs.  A  single  violin  player  is  his  own  conductor;  an 
orchestra  requires  a  separate  one.  The  work  of  directing, 
superintending,  and  adjusting,  becomes  one  of  the  functions  of 
cajDital,  from  the  moment  that  the  labour  under  the  control  of 
capital,  becomes  co-operative.  Once  a  function  of  capital,  it 
acquires  special  characteristics. 

The  directing  motive,  the  end  and  aim  of  capitalist  produc- 
tion, is  to  extract  the  greatest  possible  amount  of  surplus- 
value,^  and  consequently  to  exploit  labour-power  to  the  greatest 
possible  extent.  As  the  number  of  the  co-operating  labourers 
increases,  so  too  does  their  resistance  to  the  domination  of 
capital,  and  with  it,  the  necessity  for  capital  to  overcome  this 
resistance  by  counter-pressure.  The  control  exercised  by  the 
capitalist  is  not  only  a  special  function,  due  to  the  nature  of 
the  social  labour-process,  and  peculiar  to  that  process,  but  it  is. 
at  the  same  time,  a  function  of  the  exploitation  of  a  social 
labour-process,  and  is  consequently  rooted  in  the  unavoidable 
antagonism  between  the  exploiter  and  the  living  and  labouring 
raw  material  he  exploits. 

Again,  in  proportion  to  the  increasing  mass  of  the  means  of 
production,  now  no  longer  the  property  of  the  labourer,  but 
of  the  capitalist,  the  necessity  increases  for  some  eifective 
control  over  the  proper  application  of  those  means.^   Moreover, 

1  "  Profits  ...  is  the  sole  end  of  trade."    (J.  Vanderlint,  1.  c,  p.  11.) 

2  That  Philistine    paper,    the    Spectator^   states   that  after  the  introduction  of 
a  sort  of  partnership  between  capitalist  and  workmen  in  the  "  Wirework  Company 


\ 


322  Capitalist  Production. 

the  co-operation  of  wage  labourers  is  entirely  brought  about 
by  the  capital  that  employs  them.  Their  union  into  one 
single  productive  body  and  the  establishment  of  a  connexion 
between  their  individual  functions,  are  matters  foreign  and 
external  to  them,  are  not  their  own  act,  but  the  act  of  the 
capital  that  brings  and  keeps  them  together.  Hence  the  con- 
nexion existing  between  their  various  labours  appears  to  them, 
ideally,  in  the  shape  of  a  preconceived  plan  of  the  capitalist, 
and  practically  in  the  shape  of  the  authority  of  the  same  capi- 
talist, in  the  shape  of  the  powerful  will  of  another,  who  sub- 
jects their  activity  to  his  aims.  If,  then,  the  control  of  the 
capitalist  is  in  substance  twofold  by  reason  of  the  twofold 
nature  of  the  process  of  production  itself, — which,  on  the  one 
hand,  is  a  social  process  for  producing  use-values,  on  the 
other,  a  process  for  creating  surplus-value — in  form  that  con- 
trol is  despotic.  As  co-operation  extends  its  scale,  this  despot- 
ism takes  forms  peculiar  to  itself.  Just  as  at  first  the  capi- 
talist is  relieved  from  actual  labour  so  soon  as  his  capital  has 
reached  that  minimum  amount  with  which  capitalist  pro- 
duction, as  such,  begins,  so  now,  he  hands  over  the  work  of 
direct  and  constant  supervision  of  the  individual  workmen, 
and  groups  of  workmen,  to  a  special  kind  of  wage  labourer 
An  industrial  army  of  workmen,  under  the  command  of  a 
capitalist,  requires,  like  a  real  army,  officers  (managers),  and 
sergeants  (foremen,  overlookers),  who,  while  the  work  is  being 
done,  command  in  the  name  of  the  capitalist.  The  work  of 
supervision  becomes  their  established  and  exclusive  function. 
When  comparing  the  mode  of  production  of  isolated  peasants 
and  artizans  with  production  by  slave  labour,  the  political 
economist  counts  this  labour  of  superintendence  among  the 
faux  frais  of  production.      But,  when  considering  the  capital- 

of  Manchester,"  "the  first  result  was  a  sudden  decrease  in  waste,  the  men  not 
seeing  why  they  should  waste  their  own  property  any  more  than  any  other 
master's,  and  waste  is,  perhaps,  next  to  bad  debts,  the  greatest  source  of  manufactur- 
ing loss."  The  same  paper  finds  that  the  main  defect  in  the  Kochdale  co-operative 
experiments  is  this  :  *  *  They  showed  that  associations  of  workmen  could  manage 
shops,  mills,  and  almost  all  forms  of  industry  with  success,  and  they  immediately 
improved  the  condition  of  the  men  ;  but  then  they  did  not  leave  a  clear  place  for 
jnasters, "    Quelle  horreur  ! 

>  Professor  Cairns,  after  stating  that  the  superintendence  of  labour  is  a  leading 


\^ 


Co-Operation,  323 

ist  mode  of  production,  he,  on  the  contrary,  treats  the  work 
of  control  made  necessary  by  the  co-operative  character  of  the 
labour  process  as  identical  with  the  different  work  of  control, 
necessitated  by  the  capitalist  character  of  that  process  and  the 
antagonism  of  interests  between  capitalist  and  labourer/  It 
is  not  because  he  is  a  leader  of  industry  that  a  man  is  a 
capitalist ;  on  the  contrary,  he  is  a  leader  of  industry  because 
be  is  a  capitalist.  The  leadership  of  industry  is  an  attribute 
of  capital,  just  as  in  feudal  times  the  functions  of  general  and 
judge  were  attributes  of  landed  property .^ 

The  labourer  is  the  owner  of  his  labour-power  until  he  has 
done  bargaining  for  its  sale  with  the  capitalist ;  and  he  can 
sell  no  more  than  what  he  has — -i.e.,  his  individual,  iso- 
lated labour-power.  This  state  of  things  is  in  no  way  altered 
by  the  fact  that  the  capitalist,  instead  of  buying  the  labour- 
power  of  one  man,  buys  that  of  100,  and  enters  into  separate 
contracts  with  100  unconnected  men  instead  of  with  one.  He 
is  at  liberty  to  set  the  100  men  to  work,  without  letting  them 
co-operate.  He  pays  them  the  value  of  100  independent 
■Jabour-powers,  but  he  does  not  pay  for  the  combined  labour- 
/power  of  the  hundred.  Being  independent  of  each  other,  the 
labourers  are  isolated  persons,  who  enter  into  relations  with 
the  capitalist,  but  not  with  one  another.  This  co-operation 
begins  only  with  the  labour  process,  but  they  have  then  ceased 
to  belong  to  themselves.  On  entering  that  process,  they  be- 
come incorporated  with  capital.  As  co-operators,  as  members 
of  a  working  organism,  they  are  but  special  modes  of  existence 
of  capital.  Hence,  the  productive  power  developed  by  the 
labourer   when   working   in   co-operation,   is   the   productive 

feature  of  production  by  slaves  in  the  Southern  States  of  North  America,  continues  : 
"  The  peasant  proprietor  (of  the  North),  appropriating  the  whole  produce  of  his  toil, 
needs  no  other  stimulus  to  exertion.  Superintendence  is  here  completely  dispensed 
with."    (Cairnes,  1.  c,  pp.  48,  49.) 

1  Sir  James  Steuart,  a  writer  altogether  remarkable  for  his  quick  eye  for  the 
characteristic  social  distinctions  between  different  modes  of  production,  says  :  "Why 
do  large  undertakings  in  the  manufacturing  way  ruin  private  industry,  but  by  coming 
nearer  to  the  simplicity  of  slaves  ? "  ("  Prin.  of  Pol.  Econ.,"  London,  1767,  v.  I.,  p. 
167,  168.) 

2  Auguste  Comte  and  his  school  might  therefore  have  shown  that  feudal  lords  are 
an  eternal  necessity  in  the  same  way  that  they  have  done  in  the  case  of  the  lords 
of  capital.    , 


324  Capitalist  Production. 

power  of  capital.  This  power  is  developed  gratuitously,  when- 
ever the  workmen  are  placed  under  given  conditions,  and  it  is 
capital  that  places  them  under  such  conditions.  Because  this 
power  costs  capital  nothing,  and  because,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  labourer  himself  does  not  develop  it  before  his  labour 
belongs  to  capital,  it  appears  as  a  power  with  which  capital 
is  endowed  by  Nature — a  productive  power  that  is  immanent 
in  ca])ital. 

The  colossal  effects  of  simple  co-operation  are  to  be  seen  in 
the  gigantic  structures  of  the  ancient  Asiatics,  Egyptians, 
Etruscans,  &c.  "It  has  happened  in  times  past  that  these 
Oriental  States,  after  supplying  the  expenses  of  their  civil  and 
military  establishments,  have  found  themselves  in  possession 
of  a  surplus  which  they  could  apply  to  works  of  magnificence 
or  utility,  and  in  the  construction  of  these  their  command  over 
the  hands  and  arms  of  almost  the  entire  non-agricultural 
population  has  produced  stupendous  monuments  which  still 
indicate  their  power.  The  teeming  valley  of  the  Nile  .  .  . 
produced  food  for  a  swarming  non-agricultural  population,  and 
this  food,  belonging  to  the  monarch  and  the  priesthood,  afforded 
the  means  of  erecting  the  mighty  monuments  which  filled  the 
land.  ...  In  moving  the  colossal  statues  and  vast  masses  of 
which  the  transport  creates  wonder,  human  labour  almost 
alone,  was  prodigally  used.  .  .  .  The  number  of  the  labourers  and 
the  concentration  of  their  eflTorts  sufiiced.  We  see  mighty  coral 
reefs  rising  from  the  depths  of  the  ocean  into  islands  and  firm 
land,  yet  each  individual  depositor  is  puny,  weak,  and  con- 
temptible. The  non-agricultural  labourers  of  an  Asiatic 
monarchy  have  little  but  their  individual  bodily  exertions  to 
bring  to  the  task,  but  their  number  is  their  strength,  and  the 
power  of  directing  these  masses  gave  rise  to  the  palaces  and 
temples,  the  pyramids,  and  the  armies  of  gigantic  statues  of 
which  the  remains  astonish  and  perplex  us.  It  is  that  con- 
finement of  the  revenues  which  feed  them,  to  one  or  a  few 
hands,  which  makes  such  undertakings  possible."  ^  This  power 

1  R.  Jones.  "Text-book  of  Lectures,"  &c.,  pp.  77,  78.  The  ancient  Assyrian, 
Egyptian,  and  other  collections  in  London,  and  in  other  European  capitals,  make 
us  eye-witnesses  of  the  modes  of  carrying  on  that  co-operative  labour. 


Co-Operation.  '  325 

of  Asiatic  and  Egyptian  kings,  Etruscan  theocrats,  &;c.,  has  in 
modern  society  been  transferred  to  the  capitalist,  whether  he 
be  an  isolated,  or  as  in  joint  stock  companies,  a  collective 
capitalist. 

Co-operation,  such  as  we  find  it  at  the  dawn  of  human 
development,  among  races  who  live  by  the  chase,^  or,  say,  in 
the  agriculture  of  Indian  communities,  is  based,  on  the  one 
band,  on  ownership  in  common  of  the  means  of  production, 
and  on  the  other  hand,  on  the  fact,  that  in  those  cases,  each 
individual  has  no  more  torn  himself  ofi*  from  the  navel- 
string  of  his  tribe  or  community,  than  each  bee  has  freed 
itself  from  connexion  with  the  hive.  Such  co-operation  is 
distinguished  from  capitalistic  co-operation  by  both  of  the 
above  characteristics.  The  sporadic  application  of  co-operation 
on  a  large  scale  in  ancient  times,  in  the  middle  ages,  and  in 
modern  colonies,  reposes  on  relations  of  dominion  and  servi- 
tude, principally  on  slavery.  The  capitalistic  form,  on  the 
contrary,  presupposes  from  first  to  last,  the  free  wage  labourer, 
who  sells  his  labour-power  to  capital.  Historically,  however, 
this  form  is  developed  in  opposition  to  peasant  agriculture 
and  to  the  carrying  on  of  independent  handicrafts  whether  in 
guilds  or  not."  From  the  standpoint  of  these,  capitalistic  co- 
operation does  not  manifest  itself  as  a  particular  historical 
form  of  co-operati(m,  but  co-operation  itself  appears  to  be  a 
historical  form  peculiar  to,  and  specifically  distinguishing,  the 
capitalist  process  of  production. 

Just  as  the  social  productive  power  of  labour  that  is  de- 
veloped by  co-operation,  appears  to  be  the  productive  power 
of  capital,  so  co-operation  itself,  contrasted  with  the  process  of 
production  carried  on  by  isolated  independent  labourers,  or 
even  by  small  employers,  appears  to  be  a  specific  form  of  the 

1  Linguet  is  probably  right,  when  in  his  "Theorie  des  Lois  Civiles,"  he  declares 
hunting  to  be  the  first  form  of  co-operation,  and  man-hunting  (war)  one  of  the  earliest 
forms  of  hunting. 

2  Peasant  agriculture  on  a  small  scale,  and  the  carrying  on  of  independent  handi- 
crafts, which  together  form  the  basis  of  the  feudal  mode  of  production,  and  after 
the  dissolution  of  that  system,  continue  side  by  side  with  the  capitalist  mode,  also 
form  the  economic  foundation  of  the  classical  communities  at  their  best,  after  the 
primitive  form  of  ownership  of  land  in  common  had  disappeared,  and  before  slavery 
had  seized  on  production  in  earnest. 


326  Capitalist  P^^oduction, 

capitalist  process  of  production.  It  is  the  first  change  experi- 
enced by  the  actual  labour-process,  when  subjected  to  capi  tal 
This  change  takes  place  spontaneously.  The  simultaneous 
employment  of  a  large  number  of  wage-labourers,  in  one  and 
the  same  process,  which  is  a  necessary  condition  of  this  change, 
also  forms  the  starting  point  of  capitalist  production.  This 
point  coincides  with  the  birth  of  capital  itself.  If  then,  on  the 
one  hand,  the  capitalist  mode  of  production  presents  itself  to 
us  historically,  as  a  necessary  condition  to  the  transformation 
of  the  labour-process  into  a  social  process,  so,  on  the  other  hand, 
this  social  form  of  the  labour-process  presents  itself,  as  a  method 
employed  by  capital  for  the  more  profitable  exploitation  of 
labour,  by  increasing  that  labour's  productiveness. 

In  the  elementary  form,  under  which  we  have  hitherto 
viewed  it,  co-operation  is  a  necessary  concomitant  of  all  pro- 
duction on  a  large  scale,  but  it  does  not,  in  itself,  represent 
a  fixed  form  characteristic  of  a  particular  epoch  in  the  develop- 
ment of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production.  At  the  most  it 
appears  to  do  so,  and  that  only  approximately,  in  the  handi- 
craft-like beginnings  of  manufacture,^  and  in  that  kind  of 
agriculture  on  a  large  scale,  which  corresponds  to  the  epoch  of 
manufacture,  and  is  distinguished  from  peasant  agriculture, 
mainly  by  the  number  of  the  labourers  simultaneously  em- 
ployed, and  by  the  mass  of  the  means  of  production  con- 
centrated for  their  use.  Simple  co-operation  is  always  the 
prevailing  form,  in  those  branches  of  production  in  which 
capital  operates  on  a  large  scale,  and  division  of  labour  and 
machinery  play  but  a  subordinate  part. 

Co-operation  ever  constitutes  the  fundamental  form  of  the 
capitalist  mode  of  production ;  nevertheless,  the  elementary 
form  of  co-operation  continues  to  subsist  as  a  particular  form 
of  capitalist  production  side  by  side  with  the  more  developed 
forms  of  that  mode  of  production. 

**  Whether  the  united  skill,  industry,  and  emulation  of  many  together  on  the 
same  work  be  not  the  way  to  advance  it?  And  whether  it  had  been  otherwise 
I>ossible  for  England,  to  have  carried  on  her  Woollen  Manufacture  to  so  great  a  per- 
fection?"   (Berkeley.     **The  Querist."    London,  1750,  p.  56,  par.  521.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,  327 

CHAPTER  XIV. 

DIVISION  OF  LABOUR  AND  MANUFACTURE. 

SECTION  1. — TWOFOLD  ORIGIN  OF  MANUFACTURE. 

That  co-operation  which  is  based  on  division  of  labour,  assumes 
its  typical  form  in  manufacture,  and  is  the  prevalent  character- 
istic form  of  the  capitalist  process  of  production  throughout 
the  manufacturing  period  properly  so  called.  That  period, 
roughly  speaking,  extends  from  the  middle  of  the  16th  to  the 
last  third  of  the  18th  century. 

Manufacture  takes  its  rise  in  two  ways : — 

(1.)  By  the  assemblage,  in  one  workshop  under  the  control 
of  a  single  capitalist,  of  labourers  belonging  to  various  inde- 
pendent handicrafts,  but  through  whose  hands  a  given  article 
must  pass  on  its  way  to  completion.  A  carriage,  for  example, 
was  formerly  the  product  of  the  labour  of  a  great  number  of  inde- 
pendent artificers,  such  as  wheelwrights,  harness-makers,  tailors, 
locksmiths,upholsterers,  turners,  fringe-makers,glaziers,  painters, 
polishers,  gilders,  &c.  In  the  manufacture  of  carriages,  how- 
ever, all  these  different  artificers  are  assembled  in  one  build- 
ing, where  they  work  into  one  another's  hands.  It  is  true  that 
a  carriage  cannot  be  gilt  before  it  has  been  made.  But  if  a 
number  of  carriages  are  being  made  simultaneously,  some  may 
be  in  the  hands  of  the  gilders  while  others  are  going  through  an 
earlier  process.  So  far,  we  are  still  in  the  domain  of  simple 
co-operation,  which  finds  its  materials  ready  to  hand  in  the 
shape  of  men  and  things.  But  very  soon  an  important  change 
takes  place.  The  tailor,  the  locksmith,  and  the  other  artificers, 
being  now  exclusively  occupied  in  carriage-making,  each  gradu- 
ally loses,  through  want  of  practice,  the  'ability  to  carry  on,  to 
its  full  extent,  his  old  handicraft.  But,  on  the  other  hand,  his 
activity  now  confined  in  one  groove,  assumes  the  form  best 
adapted  to  the  narrowed  sphere  of  action.  At  first,  carriage 
manufacture  is  a  combination  of  various  independent  handi- 
crafts.    By  degrees,  it  becomes  the  splitting  up  of  carriage 


328  Capitalist  Production. 

making  into  its  various  detail  processes,  each  of  which 
crystallizes  into  the  exclusive  function  of  a  particular  work- 
man, the  manufacture,  as  a  whole,  being  carried  on  by  the  men 
in  conjunction.  In  the  same  way,  cloth  manufacture,  as  also  a 
whole  series  of  other  manufactures,  arose  by  combining 
different  handicrafts  together  under  the  control  of  a  single 
capitalist.^ 

(2.)  Manufacture  also  arises  in  a  way  exactly  the  reverse  of 
this — namely,  by  one  capitalist  employing  simultaneously  in 
one  workshop  a  number  of  artificers,  who  all  do  the  same,  or 
the  same  kind  of  work,  such  as  making  paper,  type,  or  needles. 
This  is  co-operation  in  its  most  elementary  form.  Each  of 
these  artificers  (with  the  help,  perhaps,  of  one  or  two  appren- 
tices), makes  the  entire  commodity,  and  he  consequently 
performs  in  succession  all  the  operations  necessary  for  its 
production.  He  still  works  in  his  old  handicraft-like  way. 
But  very  soon  external  circumstances  cause  a  different  use  to 
be  made  of  the  concentration  of  the  workmen  on  one  spot,  and 
of  the  simultaneousness  of  their  work.  An  increased  quantity 
of  the  article  has  perhaps  to  be  delivered  within  a  given  time. 
The  work  is  therefore  re-distributed.  Instead  of  each  man 
being  allowed  to  perform  all  the  various  operations  in  succes- 
sion, these  operations  are  changed  into  disconnected,  isolated 
ones,  carried  on  side  by  side ;  each  is  assigned  to  a  different 
artificer,  and  the  whole  of  them  together  are  performed  simul- 
taneously by  the  co-operating  workmen.  This  accidental 
repartition  gets  repeated,  developes  advantages  of  its  own,  and 
gradually  ossifies  into  a  systematic  division  of  labour.     The 

1  To  give  a  more  modern  instance  :  The  silk  spinning  and  weaving  of  Lyons  and 
Nimes  "  est  toute  patriarcale  ;  elle  emploie  beaucoup  de  femmes  et  d'enfants,  mais 
sans  les  epuiser  ni  les  corrompre  ;  elle  les  laisse  dans  leur  belles  vallees  de  la  Dr6me, 
du  Var,  de  I'lsere,  de  Vaucluse,  pour  y  elever  des  vers  et  divider  leurs  cocons  ;  jamais 
elle  n'entre  dans  une  veritable  fabrique.  Pour  6fcreaussibienobserv6  .  .  .  le  principe 
de  la  division  du  travail  s'y  rev6t  d'un  caractere  special.  H  y  a  bien  des  devideuses, 
des  moulineurs,  des  teinturiers,  des  encoUeurs,  puis  des  tisserands ;  mais  ils  ne  sont  pas 
reunis  dans  un  meme  ^tablissement,  ne  dependent  pas  d'un  m^rae  maltre ;  tons  ils 
sont  ind^pendants."  (A.  Blanqui :  "  Cours  d'Econ.  Industrielle, "  Recueilli  par  A. 
Blaise.  Paris,  1838-39,  pp.  79).  Since  Blanqui  wrote  this,  the  various  independent 
labourers  have,  to  some  extent,  been  united  in  factories.  [And  since  Marx  wrote 
the  above,  the  powerloom  has  invaded  these  factories,  and  is  now — 1886— rapidly 
superseding  the  handloom.     Ed.] 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture.         329 

commodity,  from  being  the  individual  product  of  an  inde- 
pendent artificer,  becomes  the  social  product  of  a  union  of 
artificers,  each  of  whom  performs  one,  and  only  one,  of  the 
constituent  partial  operations.  The  same  operations  which,  in 
the  case  of  a  papermaker  belonging  to  a  German  Guild,  merged 
one  into  the  other  as  the  successive  acts  of  one  artificer,  became 
in  the  Dutch  paper  manufacture  so  many  partial  operations 
carried  on  side  by  side  by  numerous  co-operating  labourers. 
The  needlemaker  of  the  Nuremberg  Guild  was  the  corner- 
stone on  which  the  English  needle  manufacture  was  raised. 
But  while  in  Nuremberg  that  single  artificer  performed  a  series 
of  perhaps  20  operations  one  after  another,  in  England  it  was 
not  long  before  there  were  20  needlemakers  side  by  side,  each 
performing  one  alone  of  those  20  operations ;  and  in  conse- 
quence of  further  experience,  each  of  those  20  operations  was 
again  split  up,  isolated,  and  made  the  exclusive  function  of  a 
separate  workman. 

The  mode  in  which  manufacture  arises,  its  growth  out  of 
handicrafts,  is  therefore  twofold.  On  the  one  hand,  it  arises 
from  the  union  of  various  independent  handicrafts,  which  become 
stripped  of  their  independence  and  specialised  to  such  an  extent 
as  to  be  reduced  to  mere  supplementary  partial  processes  in  the 
production  of  one  particular  commodity.  On  the  other  hand, 
it  arises  from  the  co-operation  of  artificers  of  one  handicraft ; 
it  splits  up  that  particular  handicraft  into  its  various  detail 
operations,  isolating,  and  making  these  operations  independent 
of  one  another  up  to  the  point  where  each  becomes  the  exclusive 
function  of  a  particular  labourer.  On  the  one  hand,  therefore, 
manufacture  either  introduces  division  of  labour  into  a  process 
of  production,  or  further  developes  that  division  ;  on  the  other 
hand,  it  unites  together  handicrafts  that  were  formerly  separate. 
But  whatever  may  have  been  its  particular  starting  point,  its 

1  final  form  is  invariably  the  same — a  productive  mechanism 
whose  parts  are  human  beings. 

For  a  proper  understanding  of  the  division  of  labour  in 
manufacture,  it  is  essential  that  the  following  points  be  firmly 
grasped.  First,  the  decomposition  of  a  process  of  production 
into  its  various  successive  steps  coincides,  here,  strictly  with 


330  Capitalist  Production. 

the  resolution  of  a  handicraft  into  its  successive  manual 
operations.  Whether  complex  or  simple,  each  operation  has 
to  be  done  by  hand,  retains  the  character  of  a  handicraft,  and 
is  therefore  dependent  on  the  strength,  skill,  quickness,  and 
sureness,  of  the  individual  workman  in  handling  his  tools. 
The  handicraft  continues  to  be  the  basis.  This  narrow 
technical  basis  excludes  a  really  scientific  analysis  of  any 
definite  process  of  industrial  production,  since  it  is  still  a  con- 
dition that  each  detail  process  gone  through  by  the  product 
must  be  capable  of  being  done  by  hand  and  of  forming,  in  its 
way,  a  separate  handicraft.  It  is  just  because  handicraft  skill 
continues,  in  this  way,  to  be  the  foundation  of  the  process  of 
production,  that  each  workman  becomes  exclusively  assigned 
to  a  partial  function,  and  that  for  the  rest  of  his  life,  his  labour- 
power  is  turned  into  the  organ  of  this  detail  function. 

Secondly,  this  division  of  labour  is  a  particular  sort  of  co- 
operation, and  many  of  its  disadvantages  spring  from  the 
general  character  of  co-operation,  and  not  from  this  particular 
form  of  it. 

SECTION  2.— THE  DETAIL  LABOURER  AND  HIS  IMPLEMENTS. 

If  we  now  go  more  into  detail,  it  is,  in  the  first  place,  clear 
that  a  labourer  who  all  his  life  performs  one  and  the  same 
simple  operation,  converts  his  whole  body  into  the  automatic, 
specialised  implement  of  that  operation.  Consequently,  he 
takes  less  time  in  doing  it,  than  the  artificer  who  performs  a 
whole  series  of  operations  in  succession.  But  the  collective 
labourer,  who  constitutes  the  living  mechanism  of  manufacture, 
is  made  up  solely  of  such  specialised  detail  labourers.  Hence, 
in  comparison  with  the  independent  handicraft,  more  is  pro- 
duced in  a  given  time,  or  the  productive  power  of  labour  is 
increased.^  Moreover,  when  once  this  fractional  work  is  es- 
tablished as  the  exclusive  function  of  one  person,  the  methods 
it   employs    become    perfected.      The    workman's    continued 

1  "The  more  any  manufacture  of  much  variety  shall  be  distributed  and  assigned 
to  different  artists,  the  same  must  needs  be  better  done  and  with  greater  expedition, 
with  less  loss  of  time  and  labour."  ("  The  Advantages  of  the  East  India  Trade," 
Lond.,  1720.  p.  71.) 


Division  of  Labour  a7id  Manufacture.        331 

repetition  of  the  same  simple  act,  and  the  concentration  of  his 
attention  on  it,  teach  him  by  experience  how  to  attain  the 
desired  effect  with  the  minimum  of  exertion.  But  since  there 
are  always  several  generations  of  labourers  living  at  one  time, 
and  working  together  at  the  manufacture  of  a  given  article, 
the  technical  skill,  the  tricks  of  the  trade  thus  acquired, 
become  established,  and  are  accumulated  and  handed  down.^ 
Manufacture,  in  fact,  produces  the  skill  of  the  detail  labourer, 
by  reproducing,  and  systematically  driving  to  an  extreme 
within  the  workshop,  the  naturally  developed  differentiation  of 
trades,  which  it  found  ready  to  hand  in  society  at  large.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  conversion  of  fractional  work  into  the  life- 
calling  of  one  man,  corresponds  to  the  tendency  shown  by 
earlier  societies,  to  make  trades  hereditary  ;  either  to  petrify 
them  into  castes,  or  whenever  definite  historical  conditions 
beget  in  the  individual  a  tendency  to  vary  in  a  manner  incom- 
patible with  the  nature  of  castes,  to  ossify  them  into  guilds. 
Castes  and  guilds  arise  from  the  action  of  the  same  natural 
law,  that  regulates  the  differentiation  of  plants  and  animals 
into  species  and  varieties,  except  that,  when  a  certain  degree 
of  development  has  been  reached,  the  heredity  of  castes  and 
the  exclusiveness  of  guilds  are  ordained  as  a  law  of  society. 
"  The  muslins  of  Dakka  in  fineness,  the  calicoes  and  other  piece 
goods  of  Coromandel  in  brilliant  and  durable  colours,  have 
never  been  surpassed.  Yet  they  are  produced  without  capital, 
machinery,  division  of  labour,  or  any  of  those  means  which 
give  such  facilities  to  the  manufacturing  interest  of  Europe. 
The  weaver  is  merely  a  detached  individual,  working  a  web 

1  "Easy  labour  is  transmitted  skill."  (Th.  Hodgskin,  1.  c.  p.  125). 

2  **  The  arts  also  have  ...  in  Egypt  reached  the  requisite  degree  of  perfection. 
For  it  is  the  only  country  where  artificers  may  not  in  any  way  meddle  with  the 
affairs  of  at  other  class  of  citizens,  but  must  follow  that  calling  alone  which  by  law  is 

hereditary  in  tiieir  clan In  other  countries  it  is  found  that  tradesman  divide 

their  attention  between  too  many  objects.  At  one  time  they  try  agriculture,  at 
another  they  take  to  commerce,  at  another  they  busy  themselves  with  two  or  three 
occupations  at  once.     In  free  countries,  they  mostly  frequent  the  assemblies  of  the 

people In  Egypt,  on  the  contrary,  every  artificer  is  severely  punished  if  he 

meddles  with  affairs  of  State,  or  carries  on  several  trades  at  once.  Thus  there  is 
nothing  to  disturb  their  application  to  their  calling.  .  .  .  Moreover,  since  they  in- 
herit from  their  forefathers  numerous  rules,  they  are  eager  to  discover  fresh 
advantages."    (Diodorus  Siculus:  Bibl.  Hist.  1.  1.  c.  74.) 


S3^  Capitalist  Production, 

when  ordered  of  a  customer,  and  with  a  loom  of  the  rudest 
construction,  consisting  sometimes  of  a  few  branches  or  bars  of 
wood,  put  roughly  together.  There  is  even  no  expedient  for 
rolling  up  the  warp ;  the  loom  must  therefore  be  kept 
stretched  to  its  full  length,  and  becomes  so  inconveniently 
large,  that  it  cannot  be  contained  within  the  hut  of  the 
manufacturer,  who  is  therefore  compelled  to  ply  his  trade  in 
the  open  air,  where  it  is  interrupted  by  every  vicissitude  of 
the  weather."^  It  is  only  the  special  skill  accumulated  from 
generation  to  generation,  and  transmitted  from  father  to  son, 
that  gives  to  the  Hindoo,  as  it  does  to  the  spider,  this  pro- 
ficiency. And  yet  the  work  of  such  a  Hindoo  weaver  is  very 
complicated,  compared  with  that  of  a  manufacturing  labourer. 

An  artificer,  who  performs  one  after  another  the  various 
fractional  operations  in  the  production  of  a  finished  article, 
must  at  one  time  change  his  place,  at  another  his  tools.  The 
transition  from  one  operation  to  another  interrupts  the  flow 
of  his  labour,  and  creates,  so  to  say,  gaps  in  his  working  day. 
These  gaps  close  up  so  soon  as  he  is  tied  to  one  and  the  same 
operation  all  day  long;  they  vanish  in  proportion  as  the 
changes  in  his  work  diminish.  The  resulting  increased  pro- 
ductive power  is  owing  either  to  an  increased  expenditure 
of  labour-power  in  a  given  time — i.e.,  to  increased  intensity 
of  labour — or  to  a  decrease  in  the  amount  of  labour-power  un- 
productively  consumed.  The  extra  expenditure  of  power, 
demanded  by  every  transition  from  rest  to  motion,  is  made  up 
for  by  prolonging  the  duration  of  the  normal  velocity  when 
once  acquired.  On  the  other  hand,  constant  labour  of  one 
uniform  kind  disturbs  the  intensity  and  flow  of  a  man's  animal 
spirits,  which  find  recreation  and  delight  in  mere  change  of 
activity. 

The  productiveness  of  labour  depends  not  only  on  the  pro- 
ficiency of  the  workman,  but  on  the  perfection  of  his  tools. 
Tools  of  the  same  kind,  such  as  knives,  drills,  gimlets,  ham- 
mers, fcc,  may  be  employed  in  different  processes;  and  the 

1  Historical  and  descriptive  account  of  Brit.  India,  &c. ,  by  Hugh  Blurray  and  James 
Wilson,  &c.,  Edinburgh  1832.  v.  IL  p.  449.  The  Indian  loom  is  upright,  i.e.,  the 
warp  is  stretched  vertically. 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,         333 

same  tool  may  serve  various  purposes  in  a  single  process.  But 
so  soon  as  the  different  operations  of  a  labour-process  are  dis- 
connected the  one  from  the  other,  and  each  fractional  operation 
acquires  in  the  hands  of  the  detail  labourer  a  suitable  and 
peculiar  form,  alterations  become  necessary  in  the  implements 
that  previously  served  more  than  one  purpose.  The  direction 
taken  by  this  change  is  determined  by  the  difficulties  ex- 
perienced in  consequence  of  the  unchanged  form  of  the  imple- 
ment. Manufacture  is  characterized  by  the  differentiation  of 
the  instruments  of  labour — a  differentiation  whereby  imple- 
ments of  a  given  sort  acquire  fixed  shapes,  adapted  to  each 
particular  application,  and  by  the  specialisation  of  those  in- 
struments, giving  to  each  special  implement  its  full  play  only 
in  the  hands  of  a  specific  detail  labourer.  In  Birmingham 
alone  500  varieties  of  hammers  are  produced,  and  not  only  is 
each  adapted  to  one  particular  process,  but  several  varieties 
often  serve  exclusively  for  the  different  operations  in  one  and 
the  same  process.  The  manufacturing  period  simplifies,  im- 
proves, and  multiplies  the  implements  of  labour,  by  adapting 
them  to  the  exclusively  special  functions  of  each  detail  la- 
bourer.^ It  thus  creates  at  the  same  time  one  of  the  material 
conditions  for  the  existence  of  machinery,  which  consists  of  a 
combination  of  simple  instruments. 

The  detail  labourer  and  his  implements  are  the  simplest 
elements  of  manufacture.  Let  us  now  turn  to  its  aspect  as  a 
whole. 

SECTION  3. — THE  TWO   FUNDAMENTAL  FORMS   OF  MANUFACTURE  I 
HETEROGENEOUS   MANUFACTURE,    SERIAL  MANUFACTURE. 

The  organisation  of  manufacture  has  two  fundamental  forms, 
which,  in  spite  of  occasional  blending,  are  essentially  different 

1  Darwin  in  his  epoch-making  work  on  the  origin  of  species,  remarks,  with  reference 
to  the  natural  organs  of  plants  and  animals,  "  So  long  as  one  and  the  same  organ  has 
diflferent  kinds  of  work  to  perform,  a  ground  for  its  changeability  may  possibly  be 
found  in  this,  that  natural  selection  preserves  or  suppresses  each  small  variation  of 
form  less  carefully  than  if  that  organ  were  destined  for  one  special  purpose  alone. 
Thus,  knives  that  are  adapted  to  cut  all  sorts  of  things,  may,  on  the  whole,  be  of  one 
shape  ;  but  an  implement  destined  to  be  used  exclusively  in  one  way  must  have  a 
different  shape  for  every  differeixt  use." 


334  Capitalist  Production. 

in  kind,  and,  moreover,  play  very  distinct  parts  in  the  sub- 
sequent transformation  of  manufacture  into  modern  industry 
carried  on  by  machinery.  This  double  character  arises  from 
the  nature  of  the  article  produced.  This  article  either  results 
from  the  mere  mechanical  fitting  together  of  partial  products 
made  independently,  or  owes  its  completed  shape  to  a  series  of 
connected  processes  and  manipulations. 

A  locomotive,  for  instance,  consists  of  more  than  5000  inde- 
pendent parts.  It  cannot,  however,  serve  as  an  example  of 
the  first  kind  of  genuine  manufacture,  for  it  is  a  structure 
produced  by  modern  mechanical  industry.  But  a  watch  can  ; 
and  William  Petty  used  it  to  illustrate  the  division  of  labour 
in  manufacture.  Formerly  the  individual  work  of  a  Nurem- 
berg artificer,  the  watch  has  been  transformed  into  the  social 
product  of  an  immense  number  of  detail  labourers,  such  as 
mainspring  makers,  dial  makers,  spiral  spring  makers,  jewelled 
hole  makers,  ruby  lever  makers,  hand  makers,  case  makers, 
screw  makers,  gilders,  with  numerous  sub-divisions,  such  as 
wheel  makers  (brass  and  steel  separate),  pin  makers,  movement 
makers,  acheveur  de  pignon  (fixes  the  wheels  on  the  axles, 
polishes  the  facets,  &;c.),  pivot  makers,  planteur  de  finissage 
(puts  the  wheels  and  springs  in  the  works),  finisseur  de  barillet 
(cuts  teeth  in  the  wheels,  makes  the  holes  of  the  right  size, 
&;c.),  escapement  makers,  cylinder  makers  for  cylinder  escape- 
ments, escapement  wheel  makers,  balance  wheel  makers,  ra- 
quette  makers  (apparatus  for  regulating  the  watch),  the 
planteur  d'echappement  (escapement  maker  proper) ;  then  the 
repasseur  de  barillet  (finishes  the  box  for  the  spring,  &c.), 
steel  polishers,  wheel  polishers,  screw  polishers,  figure  painters, 
dial  enamellers  (melt  the  enamel  on  the  copper),  fabricant  de 
pendants  (makes  the  ring  by  which  the  case  is  hung),  finisseur 
de  charniere  (puts  the  brass  hinge  in  the  cover,  &;c.),  faiseur  de 
secret  (puts  in  the  springs  that  open  the  case),  graveur,  ciseleur, 
polisseur  de  boite,  fcc,  &;c.,  and  last  of  all  the  repasseur,  who 
fits  together  the  whole  watch  and  hands  it  over  in  a  going 
state.  Only  a  few  parts  of  the  watch  pass  through  several 
hands;  and  all  these  membra  disjecta  come  together  for  the 
first  time  in  the  hand  that  binds  them  into  one  mechanical 


Division  of  Labour  and  Mamifacture.         335 

whole.  This  external  relation  between  the  finished  product, 
and  its  various  and  diverse  elements  makes  it,  as  well  in  this 
case  as  in  the  case  of  all  similar  finished  articles,  a  matter  of 
chance  whether  the  detail  labourers  are  brought  together  in 
one  workshop  or  not.  The  detail  operations  may  further  be 
carried  on  like  so  many  independent  handicrafts,  as  they  are 
in  the  Cantons  of  Vaud  and  Neu  chatel ;  while  in  Geneva  there 
exist  large  watch  manufactories  where  the  detail  labourers 
directly  co-operate  under  the  control  of  a  single  capitalist. 
And  even  in  the  latter  case  the  dial,  the  springs,  and  the  case, 
are  seldom  made  in  the  factory  itself.  To  carry  on  the  trade 
as  a  manufacture,  with  concentration  of  workmen,  is,  in  the 
watch  trade,  profitable  only  under  exceptional  conditions,  be- 
cause competition  is  greater  between  the  labourers  who  desire 
to  work  at  home,  and  because  the  splitting  up  of  the  work 
into  a  number  of  heterogeneous  processes,  permits  but  little 
use  of  the  instruments  of  labour  in  common,  and  the  capitalist, 
by  scattering  tlie  work,  saves  the  outlay  on  w^orkshops,  &c.^ 
Nevertheless  the  position  of  this  detail  labourer  who,  though 
he  works  at  home,  does  so  for  a  capitalist  (manufacturer, 
^tablisseur),  is  very  different  from  that  of  the  independent 
artificer,  who  works  for  his  own  customers.'* 

The  second  kind  of  nianufacture,  its  perfected  form,  pro- 
duces articles  that  go  through  connected  phases  of  develop- 

1  In  the  year  1854  Geneva  produced  80,000  watches,  which  is  not  one-fifth  of  the 
production  in  the  Canton  of  Neu  ch4tel.  La  Chaux-de-Fond  alone,  which  we  may 
look  upon  as  a  huge  watch  manufactory,  produces  yearly  twice  as  many  as  Geneva. 
From  1850-61  Geneva  produced  750,000  watches.  See  "  Report  from  Geneva  on  tho 
Watch  Trade"  in  "Reports  by  H.  M.'s  Secretaries  of  Embassy  and  Legation  on  the 
Manufactures,  Commerce,  &c.,  No.  6,  1863."  The  want  of  connexion  alone,  between 
the  processes  into  which  the  production  of  articles  that  merely  consist  of  parts  fitted 
together  is  split  up,  makes  it  very  difficult  to  convert  such  a  manufacture  into  a 
branch  of  modern  industry  carried  on  by  machinery  ;  but  in  the  case  of  a  watch  there 
are  two  other  impediments  in  addition,  the  minuteness  and  delicacy  of  its  parts,  and 
its  character  as  an  article  of  luxury.  Hence  their  variety,  which  is  such,  that  in  the 
best  London  houses  scarcely  a  dozen  watches  are  made  alike  in  the  course  of  a  year. 
The  watch  manufactory  of  Messrs.  Vacheron  &  Constantin,  in  which  machinery  has 
been  employed  with  success,  produces  at  the  most  three  or  four  different  varieties  of 
size  and  form. 

2  In  watchmaking,  that  classical  example  of  heterogeneous  manufacture,  we  may 
study  with  great  accuracy  the  above  mentioned  differentiation  and  specialisation  of 
the  instruments  of  labour  caused  by  the  sub-division  of  handicrafts. 


33^  Capitalist  Production. 

ment,  through  a  series  of  processes  step  by  step,  like  the  wire 
in  the  manufacture  of  needles,  which  passes  through  the  hands 
of  72  and  sometimes  even  92  different  detail  workmen. 

In  so  far  as  such  a  manufacture,  when  first  started,  com- 
bines scattered  handicrafts,  it  lessens  the  space  by  which  the 
various  phases  of  production  are  separated  from  each  other. 
The  time  taken  in  passing  from  one  stags  to  another  is 
shortened,  so  is  the  labour  that  effectuates  this  passage.^  In 
comparison  with  a  handicraft,  productive  power  is  gained,  and 
this  gain  is  owing  to  the  general  co-operative  character  of 
manufacture.  On  the  other  liand,  division  of  labour,  which  is 
the  distinguishing  principle  of  manufacture,  requires  the  isola- 
tion of  the  various  stages  of  production  and  their  independ- 
ence of  each  other.  The  establishment  and  mamtenance  of  a 
connexion  between  the  isolated  functions  necessitates  the  in- 
cessant transport  of  the  article  from  one  hand  to  another,  and 
from  one  process  to  another.  From  the  standpoint  of  modern 
mechanical  industry,  this  necessity  stands  forth  as  a  character- 
istic and  costly  disadvantage,  and  one  that  is  immanent  in  the 
principle  of  manufacture.^ 

If  we  confine  our  attention  to  some  particular  lot  of  raw 
materials,  of  I'ags,  for  instance,  in  paper  manufacture,  or  of 
wire  in  needle  manufacture,  we  perceive  that  it  passes  in 
succession  through  a  series  of  stages  in  the  hands  of  the 
various  detail  workmen  until  completion.  On  the  other  hand, 
if  we  look  at  the  workshop  as  a  whole,  we  see  the  raw  material 
in  all  the  stages  of  its  production  at  the  same  time.  The  col- 
lective labourer,  with  one  set  of  his  many  hands  armed  with 
one  kind  of  tools,  draws  the  wdre,  with  another  set,  armed 
with  different  tools,  he,  at  the  same  time,  straightens  it,  with 
another,  he  cuts  it,  with  another,  points  it,  and  so  on.  The 
difierent  detail  processes,  which  were  successive  in  time,  have 
become  simultaneous,  go  on  side  by  side  in  space.     Hence, 

1  "  In  so  close  a  cohabitation  of  the  people,  the  carriage  must  needs  be  less. "  (''  The 
Advantages  of  the  East  India  Trade,"  p.  106.) 

2  "The  isolation  of  the  different  stages  of  manufacture, . consequent  upon  the  em- 
ployment of  manual  labour,  adds  immensely  to  the  cost  of  production,  the  loss 
mainly  arising  from  the  mere  removals  from  one  process  to  another."  ("  The  Industry 
of  Nations."    Lond.,  1855.     Part  II.,  p.  200.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture.         337 

production  of  a  greater  quantum  of  finished  commodities  in  a 
given  time.^  Tliis  simultaneity,  it  is  true,  is  due  to  the 
general  co-operative  form  of  the  process  as  a  whole  ;  but 
Alanufacture  not  only  finds  the  conditions  for  co-operation 
ready  to  hand,  it  also,  to  some  extent,  creates  them  by  the 
feub-division  of  handicraft  labour.  On  the  other  hand,  it 
accomplishes  this  social  organisation  of  the  labour-process  only 
by  riveting  each  labourer  to  a  single  fractional  detail. 

Since  the  fractional  product  of  each  detail  labourer  is,  at  the 
same  time,  only  a  particular  stage  in  the  development  of  one 
and  the  same  finished  article,  each  labourer,  or  each  group  of  \ 
labourers,  prepares  the  raw  material  for  another  labourer  or 
group.  The  result  of  the  labour  of  the  one  is  the  starting 
point  for  the  labour  of  the  other.  The  one  workman  therefore 
gives  occupation  directly  to  the  other.  The  labour-time 
necessary  in  each  partial  process,  for  attaining  the  desired 
effect,  is  learnt  by  experience ;  and  the  mechanism  of  Manu- 
facture, as  a  whole,  is  based  on  the  assumption  that  a  given 
result  will  be  obtained  in  a  given  time.  It  is  only  on  this 
assumption  that  the  various  supplementary  labour-processes 
can  proceed  uninterruptedly,  simultaneously,  and  side  by  side. 
It  is  clear  that  this  direct  dependence  of  the  operations,  and 
therefore  of  the  labourers,  on  each  other,  compels  each  one  of 
them  to  spend  on  his  work  no  more  than  the  necessary  time, 
and  thus  a  continuity,  uniformity,  regularity,  order,^  and  even 
intensity  of  labour,  of  quite  a  different  kind,  is  begotten  than 
is  to  be  found  in  an  independent  handicraft  or  even  in  simple 
co-operation.  The  rule,  that  the  labour-time  expended  on  a 
commodity  should  not  exceed  that  which  is  socially  necessary 
for  its  production,  appears,  in  the  production  of  commodities 
generally,  to  be  established  by  the  mere  effect  of  competition  ; 

1  "It  (the  divisioQ  of  labour)  produces  also  an  economy  of  time  by  separating  the 
work  into  its  different  branches,  all  of  which  may  be  carried  on  into  execution  at  the 
same  moment.  .  .  By  carrying  on  all  the  different  processes  at  once,  which  an  in- 
dividual must  have  executed  separately,  it  becomes  possible  to  produce  a  multitude 
of  pins  completely  finished  in  the  same  time  as  a  single  pin  might  have  been  either 
cut  or  pointed."    (Dugald  Stewart,  1.  c,  p.  319.) 

2  * '  The  more  variety  of  artists  to  every  manufacture  .  .  .  the  greater  the  order 
and  regularity  of  every  work,  the  same  must  needs  be  done  in  less  time,  the  labour 
must  be  less."    (  "  The  Advantages,"  &c.,  p.  68.) 

Y 


SS^  Capitalist  Production. 

since,  to  express  ourselves  superficially,  each  single  producer 
is  obliged  to  sell  his  commodity  at  its  market  price.  In 
Manufacture,  on  the  contrary,  the  turning  out  of  a  given 
quantum  of  product  in  a  given  time  is  a  technical  law  of  the 
process  of  production  itself.^ 

Different  operations  take,  however,  unequal  periods,  and  yield 
therefore,  in  equal  times  unequal  quantities  of  fractional  pro- 
ducts. If,  therefore,  the  same  labourer  has,  day  after  day,  to 
perform  the  same  operation,  there  must  be  a  difierent  number 
of  labourers  for  each  operation  ;  for  instance,  in  type  manufac- 
ture, there  are  four  founders  and  two  breakers  to  one  rubber  : 
the  founder  casts  2,000  type  an  hour,  the  breaker  breaks  up 
4,000,  and  the  rubber  polishes  8,000.  Here  we  have  again  the 
principle  of  co-operation  in  its  simplest  form,  the  simultaneous 
emploj^ment  of  many  doing  the  same  thing ;  only  now,  this 
principle  is  the  expression  of  an  oi-ganic  relation.  The  division 
of  labour,  as  carried  out  in  Manufacture,  not  only  simplifies  and 
multiplies  the  qualitatively  different  parts  of  the  social  collec- 
tive labourer,  but  also  creates  a  fixed  mathematical  relation  or 
ratio  which  regulates  the  quantitative  extent  of  those  parts — 
i.e.^  the  relative  number  of  labourers,  or  the  relative  size  of  the 
group  of  labourers,  for  each  detail  operation.  It  developes, 
along  with  the  qualitative  sub-division  of  the  social  labour 
process,  a  quantitative  rule  and  proportionality  for  that 
process. 

When  once  the  most  fitting  proportion  has  been  experi- 
mentally established  for  the  numbers  of  the  detail  labourers  in 
the  various  groups  when  producing  on  a  given  scale,  that  scale 
can  be  extended  only  by  employing  a  multiple  of  each  particu- 
lar group.''     There  is  this  to  boot,  that  the  same  individual  can 

'  Nevertheless,  the  manufacturing  system,  in  many  branches  of  industry,  attains 
this  result  but  very  imperfectly,  because  it  knows  not  how  to  control  with  certainty 
the  general  chemical  and  physical  conditions  of  the  process  of  production. 

2  "  When  (from  the  peculiar  nature  of  the  produce  of  each  manufactory),  the  num- 
ber of  processes  into  which  it  is  most  advantageous  to  divide  it  is  ascertained,  as  well 
as  the  number  of  individuals  to  be  employed,  then  all  other  manufactories  which  do 
not  employ  a  direct  multiple  of  this  number  will  produce  the  article  at  a  greater  cost. 
,  .  .  Hence  arises  one  of  the  causes  of  the  great  size  of  manufacturing  establish- 
ments." (C.  Babbage.  "  On  the  Economy  of  Machinery,"  1st  ed.  London,  1832. 
Ch.  xxi.,  p.  172-173  ) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture.         339 

do  certain  kinds  of  work  just  as  well  on  a  large  as  on  a  small 
scale  ;  for  instance,  the  labour -of  superintendence,  the  carriage 
of  the  fractional  product  from  one  stage  to  the  next,  &c.  The 
isolation  of  such  functions,  their  allotment  to  a  particular 
labourer,  does  not  become  advantageous  till  after  an  increase  in 
the  number  of  labourers  employed;  but  this  increase  must 
affect  every  group  proportionally. 

The  isolated  group  of  labourers  to  whom  any  particular 
detail  function  is  assigned,  is  made  up  of  homogeneous  ele- 
ments, and  is  one  of  the  constituent  parts  of  the  total 
mechanism.  In  many  manufactures,  however,  the  group  itself 
is  an  organised  body  of  labour,  the  total  mechanism  being  a 
repetition  or  multiplication  of  these  elementary  organisms. 
Take,  for  instance,  the  manufacture  of  glass  bottles.  It  may 
be  resolved  into  three  essentially  different  stages.  First,  the 
preliminary  stage,  consisting  of  the  preparation  of  the  com- 
ponents of  the  glass,  mixing  the  sand  and  lime,  &c.,  and  melting 
them  into  a  fluid  mass  of  glass.^  Various  detail  labourers  are 
employed  in  this  first  stage,  as  also  in  the  final  one  of  removing 
the  bottles  from  the  drying  furnace,  sorting  and  packing  them 
&c.  In  the  middle,  between  these  two  stages,  comes  the  glass 
melting  proper,  the  manipulation  of  the  fluid  mass.  At  each 
mouth  of  the  furnace,  there  works  a  group,  called  "  the  hole," 
consisting  of  one  bottlemaker  or  finisher,  one  blower,  one 
gatherer,  one  putter-up  or  whetter-off,  and  one  taker-in.  These 
?^N^  detail  workers  are  so  many  special  organs  of  a  single 
working  organism  that  acts  only  as  a  whole,  and  therefore  can 
operate  only  by  the  direct  co-operation  of  the  whole  five.  The 
whole  body  is  paralysed  if  but  one  of  its  members  be  wanting. 
But  a  glass  furnace  has  several  openings  (in  England  from  4  to 
6),  each  of  which  contains  an  earthenware  melting-pot  full  of 
molten  glass,  and  employs  a  similar  five-membered  group  of 
workers.  The  organisation  of  each  group  is  based  on  division 
of  labour,  but  the  bond  between  the  different  groups  is  simple 
co-operation,  which,  by  using  in  common  one  of  the  means  of 

1  In  England,  the  melting- furnace  is  distinct  from  the  glass-furnace  in  which  the 
glass  is  manipulated.  In  Belgium,  one  and  the  same  furnace  serves  for  both 
processes. 


340  Capitalist  Prodtution. 

production,  the  furnace,  causes  it  to  be  more  economically  con- 
sumed. Such  a  furnace,  with  its  4-6  groups,  constitutes  a 
glass  house ;  and  a  glass  manufactory  comprises  a  number  of 
such  glass  houses,  together  with  the  apparatus  and  workmeii 
requisite  for  the  preparatory  and  final  stages. 

Finally,  just  as  Manufacture  arises  in  part  from  the  combina- 
tion of  various  handicrafts,  so,  too,  it  developes  into  a  combina- 
tion of  various  manufactures.  The  larger  English  glass 
manufacturers,  for  instance,  make  their  own  earthenware 
melting-pots,  because,  on  the  quality  of  these  depends,  to  a 
great  extent,  the  success  or  failure  of  the  process.  The  manu- 
facture of  one  of  the  means  of  production  is  here  united  with 
that  of  the  product.  On  the  other  hand,  the  manufacture  of 
the  product  may  be  united  with  other  manufactures,  of  which 
that  product  is  the  raw  material,  or  with  the  products  of  which 
it  is  itself  subsequently  mixed.  Thus,  we  find  the  manufacture 
of  flint  glass  combined  with  that  of  glass  cutting  and  brass 
founding ;  the  latter  for  the  metal  settings  of  various  articlea 
of  glass.  The  various  manufactures  so  combined  form  more  or 
less  separate  departments  of  a  larger  manufacture,  but  are  at 
the  same  time  independent  processes,  each  with  its  own 
division  of  labour.  In  spite  of  the  many  advantages  offered  by 
this  combination  of  manufactures,  it  never  grows  into  a  complete 
technical  system  on  its  own  foundation.  That  happens  only 
on  its  transformation  into  an  industry  carried  on  by  machinery. 

Early  in  the  manufacturing  period,  the  principle  of  lessening 
the  necessary  labour-time  in  the  production  of  commodities,^ 
was  accepted  and  formulated  :  and  the  use  of  machines,  especi- 
ally for  certain  simple  first  processes  that  have  to  be  conducted 
on  a  very  large  scale,  and  with  the  application  of  great  force, 
sprang  up  here  and  there.  Thus,  at  an  early  period  in  paper 
manufacture,  the  tearing  up  of  the  rags  was  done  by  paper- 
mills;  and  in  metal  works,  the  pounding  of  tlie  ores  was 
effected  by  stamping  mills.^     The  Roman  Empire  had  handed 

1  This  can  be  seen  from  W.  Petty,  John  Bellers,  Andrew  Yarranton,  "The  Ad- 
vantages of  the  East  India  Trade,"  and  J.  Vanderlint,  not  to  mention  others. 

3  Towards  the  end  of  the  16th  century,  mortars  and  sieves  were  still  used  in  France 
for  pounding  and  washing  ores. 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,         341 

down  the  elementary  form  of  all  machinery  in  the  water- 
wheel.i 

The  handicraft  period  bequeathed  to  us  the  great  inventions 
of  the  compass,  of  gunpowder,  of  type-printing,  and  of  the 
automatic  clock.  But,  on  the  whole,  machinery  played  that 
subordinate  part  which  Adam  Smith  assigns  to  it  in  compari- 
son with  division  of  labour.^  The  sporadic  use  of  machinery 
in  the  17th  century  was  of  the  greatest  importance,  because  it 
supplied  the  great  mathematicians  of  that  time  with  a  practical 
basis  and  stimulant  to  the  creation  of  the  science  of  mechanics. 

The  collective  labourer,  formed  by  the  combination  of  a 
number  of  detail  labourers,  is  the  machinery  specially  char- 
acteristic of  the  manufacturing  period.  The  various  operations 
that  are  performed  in  turns  by  the  producer  of  a  commodity, 
and  coalesce  one  with  another  during  the  progress  of  produc- 
tion, lay  claim  to  him  in  various  wa3^s.  In  one  operation  he 
must  exert  more  strength,  in  another  more  skill,  in  another 
more  attention ;  and  the  same  individual  does  not  possess  all 
these  qualities  in  an  equal  degree.  After  Manufacture  has 
once  separated,  made  independent,  and  isol?«ted  the  various 
operations,  the  labourers  are  divided,  classified,  and  grouped 
according  to  their  predominating  qualities.  If  their  natural 
endowments  are,  on  the  one  hand,  the  foundation  on  which 
the  division  of  labour  is  built  up,  on  the  other  hand,  Manu- 
facture, once  introduced,  developes  in  them  new  powers  that 
are  by  nature  fitted  only  for  limited  and  special  functions. 
The  collective  labourer  now  possesses,  in  an  equal  degree  of 

1  The  whole  history  of  the  development  of  machinery  can  be  traced  in  the  history 
of  the  corn  mill.  The  factory  in  England  is  still  a  "  mill."  In  German  technological 
works  of  the  first  decade  of  this  century,  the  term  "  miihle  "  is  still  found  in  use,  not 
only  for  all  machinery  driven  by  the  forces  of  Nature,  but  also  for  all  manufactures 
where  apparatus  in  the  nature  of  machinery  is  applied. 

2  As  will  be  seen  more  in  detail  in  the  fourth  book  of  this  work,  Adam  Smith  has 
not  established  a  single  new  proposition  relating  to  division  of  labour.  What,  how- 
ever, characterises  him  as  the  political  economist  par  excellence  of  the  period  of 
Manufacture,  is  the  stress  he  lays  on  division  of  labour.  The  subordinate  part  which 
he  assigns  to  machinery  gave  occasion  in  the  early  days  ot  modern  mechanical  in- 
dustry to  the  polemic  of  Lauderdal*-,  and,  at  a  later  period,  to  that  of  Ure.  A.  Smith 
also  confounds  differentiation  of  the  instruments  of  labour,  in  which  the  detail 
labourers  themselves  took  an  active  part,  with  the  invention  of  machinery  ;  in  this 
latter,  it  is  not  the  workmen  in  manufactories,  but  learned  men,  handicraftsmen, 
and  even  peasants  (Brindley),  who  play  a  part. 


/ 


342  Capitalist  P reduction, 

excellence,  all  the  qualities  requisite  for  production,  and  ex- 
pends them  in  the  most  economical  manner,  by  exclusively 
employing  all  his  organs,  consisting  of  particular  labourers,  or 
groups  of  labourers,  in  performing  their  special  functions.* 
The  one-sidedness  and  the  deficiencies  of  the  detail  labourer 
become  perfections  when  he  is  a  part  of  the  collective  labourer.* 
The  habit  of  doing  only  one  thing  converts  him  into  a  never 
failing  instrument,  while  his  connexion  with  the  whole  me- 
chanism compels  him  to  work  with  the  regularity  of  the  parts 
of  a  machine.* 

Since  the  collective  labourer  has  functions,  both  simple  and 
complex,  both  high  and  low,  his  members,  the  individual 
labour-powers,  require  different  degrees  of  training,  and  must 
therefore  have  different  values.  Manufacture,  therefore,  de- 
velopes  a  hierarchy  of  labour-powers,  to  which  there  corres- 
ponds a  scale  of  wages.  If,  on  the  one  hand,  the  individual 
labourers  are  appropriated  and  annexed  for  life  by  a  limited 
function ;  on  the  other  hand,  the  various  operations  of  the 
hierarchy  are  parcelled  out  among  the  labourers  according  to 
both  their  natural  and  their  acquired  capabilities.*  Every 
process  of  production,  however,  requires  certain  simple  manip- 

1  "  The  master  manufacturer,  by  dividing  the  work  to  be  executed  into  different 
processes,  each  requiring  different  degrees  of  skill  or  of  force,  can  purchase  exactly 
that  precise  quantity  of  both  which  is  necessary  for  each  process  ;  whereas,  if  the 
whole  work  were  executed  by  one  workman,  that  person  must  possess  sufficient  skill 
to  perform  the  most  difficult,  and  sufficient  strength  to  execute  the  most  laborious  of 
the  operations  into  which  the  article  is  divided."    (Ch.  Babbage.  1.  c,  ch.  xviii.) 

2  For  instance,  abnormal  development  of  some  muscles,  curvature  of  bones,  &c. 

3  The  question  put  by  one  of  the  Inquiry  Commissioners,  How  the  young  persons 
are  kept  steadily  to  their  work,  is  very  correctly  answered  by  Mr.  Wm.  Marshall,  the 
general  manager  of  a  glass  manufactory :  "  They  cannot  well  neglect  their  work  ; 
when  they  once  begin,  they  must  go  on ;  they  are  just  the  same  as  parts  of  a 
machine."    (  "Children's  Empl.  Comm.,"  4th  Rep.,  1865,  p.  247.) 

4  Dr.  Ure,  in  his  apotheosis  of  Modern  Mechanical  Industry,  brings  out  the  peculiar 
character  of  manufacture  more  sharply  than  previous  economists,  who  had  not  his  pole- 
mical interest  in  the  matter,  and  more  sharply  even  than  his  contemporaries — Babbage, 
e,g.,  who,  though  much  his  superior  as  a  mathematician  and  mechanician,  treated  me- 
chanical industry  from  the  standpoint  of  manufacture  alone.  Ure  says,  "  This  appro- 
priation ...  to  each,  a  workman  of  appropriate  value  and  cost  was  naturally  assigned, 
forms  the  very  essence  of  division  of  labour."  On  the  other  hand,  he  describes  this 
division  as  "adaptation  of  labour  to  the  different  talents  of  men,"  and  lastly,  charac- 
terises the  whole  manufacturing  system  as  "  a  system  for  the  division  or  gradation  of 
labour,"  as  "the  division  of  labour  into  degrees  of  skill,"  &'\  (Ure,  1.  c.  pp.  19-2.^ 
passim.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,  343 

ulations,  which  every  man  is  capable  of  doing.  They  too 
are  now  severed  from  their  connexion  with  the  more  preg- 
nant moments  of  activity,  and  ossified  into  exclusive  func- 
tions of  specially  appointed  labourers.  Hence,  Manufacture 
begets,  in  every  handicraft  that  it  seizes  upon,  a  class  of  so- 
called  unskilled  labourers,  a  class  which  handicraft  industry 
strictly  excluded.  If  it  developes  a  one-sided  speciality  into  a 
perfection,  at  the  expense  of  the  whole  of  a  man's  working 
capacity,  it  also  begins  to  make  a  speciality  of  the  absence  of 
all  development.  Alongside  of  the  hierarchic  gradation  there 
steps  the  simple  separation  of  the  labourers  into  skilled  and 
unskilled.  For  the  latter,  the  cost  of  apprenticeship  vanishes  ; 
for  the  former,  it  diminishes,  compared  with  that  of  artificers, 
in  consequence  of  the  functions  being  simplified.  In  both 
cases  the  value  of  labour-power  falls.^  An  exception  to  this 
law^  holds  good  whenever  the  decomposition  of  the  labour- 
process  begets  new.  and  comprehensive  functions,  that  either 
had  no  place  at  all,  or  only  a  very  modest  one,  in  handicrafts. 
The  fall  in  the  value  of  labour-power,  caused  by  the  disap- 
pearance or  diminution  of  the  expenses  of  apprenticeship,  im- 
plies a  direct  increase  of  surplus- value  for  the  benefit  of 
capital;  for  everything  that  shortens  the  necessary  labour- 
time  required  for  the  reproduction  of  labour-power,  extends  the 
domain  of  surplus-labour. 

SECTION    4. — DIVISION    OP    LABOUR    IN    MANUFACTURE,     AND    DIVISION    OF 
LABOUR    IN    SOCIETY. 

We  first  considered  the  origin  of  Manufacture,  then  its 
simple  elements,  then  the  detail  labourer  and  his  implements, 
and  finally,  the  totality  of  the  mechanism.  We  shall  now 
lightly  touch  upon  the  relation  between  the  division  of  labour 
in  manufacture,  and  the  social  division  of  labour,  which  forms 
the  foundation  of  all  production  of  commodities. 

If  we  keep  labour  alone  in  view,  we  may  designate  the 
separation  of  social  production  into  its  main  divisions  or 
genera — viz.,  agriculture,  industries,  &c.,  as  division  of  labour 

J  *'  Each  handicraftsman  being  .  .  .  enabled  to  perfect  himself  by  practice  in  one 
point,  became  ...  a  cheaper  workman."    (Ure,  1.  c,  p.  19.) 


344  Capitalist  Production, 

in  general,  and  the  splitting  up  of  these  families  into  species 
and  sub-species,  as  division  of  labour  in  particular,  and  the 
division  of  labour  within  the  workshop  as  division  of  labour  in 
singular  or  in  detail.^ 

Division  of  labour  in  a  society,  and  the  corresponding  tying 
down  of  individuals  to  a  particular  calling,  developes  itself, 
just  as  does  the  division  of  labour  in  manufacture,  from  opposite 
starting  points.  Within  a  family,^  and  after  further  develop- 
ment within  a  tribe,  there  springs  up  naturally  a  division  of 
labour,  caused  by  differences  of  sex  and  age,  a  division  that  is 
consequently  based  on  a  purely  physiological  foundation,  which 
clivision  enlarges  its  materials  by  the  expansion  of  the  com- 
munity, by  the  increase  of  population,  and  more  especially,  by 
the  conflicts  between  different  tribes,  and  the  subjugation  of 
one  tribe  by  another.  On  the  other  hand,  as  I  have  before 
remarked,  the  exchange  of  products  springs  up  at  the  points 
where  different  families,  tribes,  communities,  come  in  contact ; 
for,  in  the  beginning  of  civilisation,  it  is  not  private  indi- 
viduals but  families,  tribes,  &c.,  that  meet  on  an  independent 
footing.  Different  communities  find  different  means  of  pro- 
duction, and  different  means  of  subsistence  in  their  natural  en- 
vironment. Hence,  their  modes  of  production,  and  of  living, 
and  their  products  are  different.  It  is  this  spontaneously  de- 
veloped difference  which,  when  different  communities  come  in 
contact,  calls  forth  the  mutual  exchange  of  products,  and  the 

1  *'  Division  of  labour  proceeds  from  the  separation  of  professions  the  most  widely 
different  to  that  division,  where  several  labourers  divide  between  them  the  preparation 
of  one  and  the  same  product,  as  in  manufacture."  (Storch  :  "  Cours  d'Econ.  Pol. 
Paris  Edn."  t.  I.,  p.  173.)  "  Nous  rencontrons  chez  les  peuples  parvenus  ^  un  certain 
degre  de  civilisation  trois  genres  de  divisions  d'industrie  :  la  premiere,  que  nous 
nommerons  g6nerale,  amene  la  distinction  des  producteurs  en  agriculteurs,  manu- 
facturiers  et  commer^ans,  elle  se  rapporte  aux  trois  principales  branches  d'industrie 
nationale ;  la  seconde,  qu'on  pourrait  appeler  speciale,  est  la  division  de  chaque  genre 
d'industrie  en  especes.  ...  la  troisierae  division  d'industrie,  celle  enfin  qu'on  devrait 
qualifier  de  division  de  la  besogne  ou  de  travail  proprement  dit,  est  celle  qui  s'etablit 
dans  les  arts  et  les  metiers  separes.  .  .  .  qui  s'6tablit  dans  la  plupart  des  manufactures 
et  des  ateliers."    (Skarbek.  1.  c.  pp.  84,  85.) 

2  Note  to  the  third  edition.  Subsequent  very  searching  study  of  the  primitive 
condition  of  man,  led  the  author  to  the  conclusion,  that  it  was  not  the  family  that 
originally  developed  into  the  tribe,  but  that,  on  the  contrary,  the  tribe  was  the  primi- 
tive and  spontaneously  developed  form  of  human  association,  on  the  basis  of  blood 
relationship,  and  that  out  of  the  first  incipient  loosening  of  the  tribal  bonds,  the 
many  and  various  forms  of  the  family  were  afterwards  developed.     (Ed.  3rd  ed.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacttire.         345 

consequent  gradual  conversion  of  those  products  into  com- 
modities. Exchange  does  not  create  the  differences  between 
the  spheres  of  production,  but  brings  what  are  already  different 
into  relation,  and  thus  converts  them  into  more  or  less  inter- 
dependent branches  of  the  collective  production  of  an  enlarged 
society.  In  the  latter  case,  the  social  division  of  labour  arises 
from  the  exchange  between  spheres  of  production,  that  are 
originally  distinct  and  independent  of  one  another.  In  the 
former,  where  the  physiological  division  of  labour  is  the  starting 
point,  the  particular  organs  of  a  compact  whole  grow  loose, 
and  break  off,  principally  owing  to  the  exchange  of  commodi- 
ties with  foreign  communities,  and  then  isolate  themselves  so 
far,  that  the  sole  bond,  still  connecting  the  various  kinds  of 
work,  is  the  exchange  of  the  products  as  commodities.  In  the 
one  case,  it  is  the  making  dependent  what  was  before  inde- 
pendent ;  in  the  other  case,  the  making  independent  what  was 
before  dependent. 

The  foundation  of  every  division  of  labour  that  is  well  de- 
veloped, and  brought  about  by  the  exchange  of  commodities,  is 
the  separation  between  town  and  country.^  It  may  be  said, 
that  the  whole  economical  history  of  societ}^  is  summed  up  in 
the  movement  of  this  antithesis.  We  pass  it  over,  however, 
for  the  present. 

Just  as  a  certain  number  of  simultaneously  employed 
labourers  are  the  material  pre-requisites  for  division  of  labour 
in  manufacture,  so  are  the  number  and  density  of  the  popula- 
tion, which  here  correspond  to  the  agglomeration  in  one 
workshop,  a  necessary  condition  for  the  division  of  labour 
in  society .'^     Nevertheless,  this  density  is  more  or  less  relative. 

1  Sir  James  Steuart  is  the  economist  who  has  handled  this  subject  best.  How 
little  his  book,  which  appeared  ten  years  before  the  "  Wealth  of  Nations,"  is  known, 
even  at  the  present  time,  may  be  judged  from  the  fact  that  the  admirers  of  JNIalthus 
do  not  even  know  that  the  first  edition  of  the  latter's  work  on  population  contains, 
except  in  the  purely  declamatory  part,  very  little  but  extracts  from  Steuart,  and  in 
a  less  degree,  from  Wallace  and  Townsend. 

2  "There  is  a  certain  density  of  population  which  is  convenient,  both  for  social 
intercourse,  and  for  that  combination  of  powers  by  which  the  produce  of  labour  is 
increased."  (James  Mill,  1.  c.  p.  50.)  *' As  the  number  of  labourers  increases,  the 
productive  jjower  of  society  augments  in  the  compound  ratio  of  that  increase,  multi- 
plied by  the  effects  of  the  division  of  labour."    (Th.  Hodgskin,  1.  c.  pp.  125,  126.) 


34^  Capitalist  Production. 

A  relatively  thinly  populated  country,  with  well-developed 
means  of  communication,  has  a  denser  population  than  a  more 
numerously  populated  country,  with  badly-developed  means  of 
communication ;  and  in  this  sense  the  Northern  States  of  the 
American  Union,  for  instance,  are  more  thickly  populated  than 
Tndia.^ 

Since  the  production  and  the  circulation  of  commodities  are 
the  general  pre-requisites  of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production, 
division  of  labour  in  manufacture  demands,  that  division  of 
labour  in  society  at  large  should  previously  have  attained 
a  certain  degree  of  development.  Inversely,  the  former 
division  reacts  upon  and  developes  and  multiplies  the 
latter.  Simultaneously,  with  the  differentiation  of  the  in- 
struments of  labour,  the  industries  that  produce  these  in- 
struments, become  more  and  more  differentiated.^  If  the 
manufacturing  system  seize  upon  an  industry,  which,  pre- 
viously, was  carried  on  in  connexion  with  others,  either  as  a 
chief  or  as  a  subordinate  industry,  and  by  one  producer,  these 
industries  immediately  separate  their  connexion,  and  become 
independent.  If  it  seize  upon  a  particular  stage  in  the  pro- 
duction of  a  commodity,  the  other  stages  of  its  production 
become  converted  into  so  many  independent  industries.  It 
has  already  been  stated,  that  where  the  finished  article  con- 
sists merely  of  a  number  of  parts  fitted  together,  the  detail 
operations  may  re-establish  themselves  as  genuine  and  sep- 
arate handicrafts.  In  order  to  carry  out  more  perfectly  the 
division  of  labour  in  manufacture,  a  single  branch  of  pro- 
duction is,  according  to  the  varieties  of  its  raw  material,  or  the 
various  forms  that  one  and  the  same  raw  material  may  assume, 
split  up  into  numerous,  and  to  some  extent,  entirely  new 
manufactures.  Accordingly,  in  France  alone,  in  the  first  half 
of  the  18th  century,  over  100  different  kinds  of  silk  stuffs 

1  In  consequence  of  the  great  demand  for  cotton  after  1861,  the  production  of 
cotton,  in  some  thickly  populated  districts  of  India,  was  extended  at  the  expense  of 
rice  cultivation.  In  consequence  there  arose  local  famins,  the  defective  means  of 
communication  not  permitting  the  failure  of  rice  in  one  district  to  be  compensated 
by  importation  from  another. 

2  Thus,  the  fabrication  of  shuttles  formed,  as  early  as  the  17th  century,  a  special 
branch  of  industry  in  Holland. 


Division  0/  Labour  and  Manufacture,         347 

were  woven,  and,  in  Avignon,  it  was  law,  that  "  every  appren- 
tice should  devote  himself  to  only  one  sort  of  fabrication,  and 
should  not  learn  the  preparation  of  several  kinds  of  stuff  at 
once."  The  territorial  division  of  labour,  which  confines 
special  branches  of  production  to  special  districts  of  a  country, 
acquires  fresh  stimulus  from  the  manufacturing  system,  which 
exploits  every  special  advantage.^  The  Colonial  system  and 
the  opening  out  of  the  markets  of  the  world,  both  of  which 
are  included  in  the  general  conditions  of  existence  of  the 
manufacturing  period,  furnish  rich  material  for  developing 
the  division  of  labour  in  society.  It  is  not  the  place,  here,  to  go 
on  to  show  how  division  of  labour  seizes  upon,  not  only  the 
economical,  but  every  other  sphere  of  society,  and  everywhere 
lays  the  foundation  of  that  all  engrossing  system  of  specialis- 
ing and  sorting  men,  that  development  in  a  man  of  one  single 
faculty  at  the  expense  of  all  other  faculties,  which  caused  A. 
Ferguson,  the  master  of  Adam  Smith,  to  exclaim  :  "  We  make 
a  nation  of  Helots,  and  have  no  free  citizens."^ 

But,  in  spite  of  the  numerous  analogies  and  links  connecting 
them,  division  of  labour  in  the  interior  of  a  society,  and  that 
in  the  interior  of  a  workshop,  differ  not  only  in  degree,  but 
also  in  kind.  The  analogy  appears  most  indisputable  where 
there  is  an  invisible  bond  uniting  the  various  branches  of 
trade.  For  instance,  the  cattle  breeder  produces  hides,  the 
tanner  makes  the  hides  into  leather,  and  the  shoemaker,  the 
leather  into  boots.  Here  the  thing  produced  by  each  of  them 
is  but  a  step  towards  the  final  form,  which  is  the  product  of 
all  their  labours  combined.  There  are,  besides,  all  the  various 
industries  that  supply  the  cattle-breeder,  the  tanner,  and  the 
shoemaker  with  the  means  of  production.  Now  it  is  quite 
possible  to  imagine,  with  Adam  Smith,  that  the  difference  be- 
tween the  above  social  division  of  labour,  and  the  division  in 

1  "Whether  the  woollen  manufacture  of  England  is  not  diWded  into  several  parts 
or  branches  appropriated  to  particular  places,  where  they  are  only  or  principally 
manufactured  ;  fine  cloths  in  Somersetshire,  coarse  in  Yorkshire,  long  ells  at  Exeter, 
soies  at  Sudbury,  crapes  at  Norwich,  linseys  at  Kendal,  blankets  at  Whitney,  and 
so  forth."    (Berkeley  :  "The  Querist,"  1750,  p.  520.) 

2  A.  Ferguson:  "  History  of  Civil  Society."  Edinburgh,  1767  ;  Part  iv.,  sect,  ii., 
p.  285. 


34^  Capitalist  Production. 

manufacture,  is  merely  subjective,  exists  merely  for  the 
observer,  who,  in  a  manufacture,  can  see  with  one  glance,  all 
the  numerous  operations  being  performed  on  one  spot,  while 
in  the  instance  given  above,  the  spreading  out  of  the  work 
over  great  areas,  and  the  gieat  number  of  people  employed  in 
each  branch  of  labour,  obscure  the  connexion.^  But  what  is 
it  that  forms  the  bond  between  the  independent  labours  of 
the  cattle-breeder,  the  tanner,  and  the  shoemaker  ?  It  is  the 
fact  that  their  respective  products  are  commodities.  What,  on 
the  other  hand,  characterises  division  of  labour  in  manufactures? 
The  fact  that  the  detail  labourer  produces  no  commodities.^ 
It  is  only  the  common  product  of  all  the  detail  labourers  that 
becomes  a  commodity.^  Division  of  labour  in  a  society  is 
brought  about  by  the  purchase  and  sale  of  the  products  of 
different  branches  of  industry,  while  the  connexion  between 

1  In  manufacture  proper,  he  says,  the  division  of  labour  appears  to  be  greater, 
because  "  those  employed  ih  every  different  branch  of  the  work  can  often  be  col- 
lected into  the  same  workhouse,  and  jjlaced  at  once  under  the  view  of  the  spectator. 
In  those  great  manufactures,  (!)  on  the  contrary,  which  are  destined  to  supply  the 
great  wants  of  the  great  body  of  the  people,  every  different  branch  of  the  work 
employs  so  great  a  number  of  workmen,  that  it  is  impossible  to  collect  them  all  into 
the  same  workhouse  .  .  .  the  division  is  not  near  so  obvious."  (A.  Smith:  "Wealth 
of  Nations,"  bk.  i.  ch.  i.)  The  celebrated  passage  in  the  same  chapter  that  begins  with 
the  words,  ' '  Observe  the  accommodation  of  the  most  common  artificer  or  day  labourer 
in  a  civilized  and  thriving  country,"&c.,  and  then  proceeds  to  depict  what  an  enormous 
number  and  variety  of  industries  contribute  to  the  satisfaction  of  the  wants  of  an 
ordinary  labourer,  is  copied  almost  word  for  word  from  B.  de  Mandeville's  Kemarks 
to  his  "Fable  of  the  Bees,  or  Private  Vices,  Publick  Benefits."  (First  ed.,  without 
the  remarks,  1706  ;  with  the  remarks,  1714.) 

2  "  There  is  no  longer  anything  which  we  can  call  the  natural  reward  of  individual 
labour.  Each  labourer  produces  only  some  part  of  a  whole,  and  each  part,  having  no 
value  or  utility  in  itself,  there  is  nothing  on  which  the  labourer  can  seize,  and  say 
It  is  my  product,  this  I  will  keep  to  myself."  ( *'  Labour  Defended  against  the  Claims 
of  Capital."  Lond.,  1825,  p.  25.)  The  author  of  this  admirable  work  is  the  Th. 
Hodgskin  I  have  already  cited. 

3  This  distinction  between  division  of  labour  in  society  and  in  manufacture,  was 
practically  illustrated  to  the  Yankees.  One  of  the  new  taxes  devised  at  Washington 
during  the  civil  war,  was  the  duty  of  6%  "  on  all  industrial  products."  Question: 
What  is  an  industrial  product?  Answer  of  the  legislature:  A  thing  is  produced 
"  when  it  is  made,"  and  it  is  made  when  it  is  ready  for  sale.  Now,  for  one  example 
out  of  many.  The  New  York  and  Philadelphia  manufacturers  had  previously  been 
in  the  habit  of  "making"  umbrellas,  with  all  their  belongings.  But  since  an 
umbrella  is  a  mixtum  compositum  of  very  heterogeneous  parts,  by  degrees  these 
parts  became  the  products  of  various  separate  industries,  carried  on  independently 
in  different  places.  They  entered  as  separate  commodities  into  the  umbrella  man- 
ufactory, where  they  were  fitted  together.     The  Yankees  have  given  to  articles  thus 


l\ 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,         349 

the  detail  operations  in  a  workshop,  are  due  to  the  sale  of  the 
labour-power  of  several  workmen  to  one  capitalist,  who  applies 
it  as  combined  labour-power.  The  division  of  labour  in  the 
workshop  implies  concentration  of  the  means  of  production  in 
the  hands  of  one  capitalist ;  the  division  of  labour  in  society 
implies  their  dispersion  among  many  independent  producers  of 
commodities.  While  within  the  workshop,  the  iron  law  of 
proportionality  subjects  definite  numbers  of  workmen  to  de- 
finite functions,  in  the  society  outside  the  workshop,  chance  and 
caprice  have  full  play  in  distributing  the  producers  and  their 
means  of  production  among  the  various  branches  of  industry. 
The  difierent  spheres  of  production,  it  is  true,  constantly  tend 
to  an  equilibrium :  for,  on  the  one  hand,  while  each  producer 
of  a  commodity  is  bound  to  produce  a  use-value,  to  satisfy  a 
particular  social  want,  and  while  the  extent  of  these  wants 
differs  quantitatively,  still  there  exists  an  inner  relation  which 
settles  their  proportions  into  a  regular  system,  and  that  system 
one  of  spontaneous  growth  ;  and,  on  the  other  hand,  the  law  of 
the  value  of  commodities  ultimately  determines  how  much  of 
its  disposable  working-time  society  can  expend  on  each  par 
ticular  class  of  commodities.  But  this  constant  tendency  to 
equilibrium,  of  the  various  spheres  of  production,  is  exercised 
only  in  the  shape  of  a  reaction  against  the  constant  upset 
ting  of  this  equilibrium.  The  a  priori  system  on  which  th 
division  of  labour,  within  the  workshop,  is  regularly  carrie 
out,  becomes  in  the  division  of  labour  within  the  society,  an  i 
posteriori,  nature-imposed  necessity,  controlling  the  lawless 
caprice  of  the  producers,  and  perceptible  in  the  barometric^  1 
fluctuations  of  the  market  prices,  Division  of  labour  withii 
the  workshop  implies  the  undisputed  authority  of  the  capita  - 
ist  over  men,  that  are  but  parts  of  a  mechani>ra  that  belong  3 
to  him.  The  division  of  labour  within  the  society  brings  int ) 
contact  independent  commodity-producers,  who  acknowledg  3 
no  other  authority  but  that  of  competition,  of  the  coercioi 
exerted  by  the  pressure  of  their  mutual  interests  ;  just  as  in  tUe 

fitted  together,  the  name  of  "assembled  articles,"  a  name  they  deserve,  for  beipg 
an  assemblage  of  taxes.  Thus  the  umbrella  "assembles,"  first,  6*^/0  on  the  price/ of 
each  of  its  elements,  and  a  further  67o  on  its  own  total  price. 


3 so  Capitalist  Production, 

animal  kingdom,  the  helluTn  omnium  contra  omnes  more  or  less 
preserves  the  conditions  of  existence  of  every  species.  The 
same  bourgeois  mind  which  praises  division  of  labour  in  the 
workshop,  life-long  annexation  of  the  labourer  to  a  partial 
operation,  and  his  complete  subjection  to  capital,  as  being  an 
organisation  of  labour  that  increases  its  productiveness — that 
same  bourgeois  mind  denounces  with  equal  vigour  every  con- 
scious attempt  to  socially  control  and  regulate  the  process  of 
production,  as  an  inroad  upon  such  sacred  things  as  the  rights 
of  property,  freedom  and  unrestricted  play  for  the  bent  of 
the  individual  capitalist.  It  is  very  characteristic  that  the 
enthusiastic  apologists  of  the  factory  system  have  nothing 
more  damning  to  urge  against  a  general  organization  of  the 
labour  of  society,  than  that  it  would  turn  all  society  into  one 
immense  factory. 

If,  in  a  society  with  capitalist  production,  anarchy  in  the 
social  division  of  labour  and  despotism  in  that  of  the  workshop 
are  mutual  conditions  the  one  of  the  other,  we  find,  on  the  con- 
trary, in  those  earlier  forms  of  society  in  which  the  separation 
of  trades  has  been  spontaneously  developed,  then  crystallized, 
and  finally  made  permanent  by  law,  on  the  one  hand,  a  speci- 
men of  the  organisation  of  the  labour  of  society,  in  accordance 
with  an  approved  and  authoritative  plan,  and  on  the  other, 
the  entire  exclusion  of  division  of  labour  in  the  workshop, 
or  at  all  events  a  mere  dwarf-like  or  sporadic  and  accidental 
development  of  the  same.^ 

Those  small  and  extremely  ancient  Indian  communities,  some 
of  which  have  continued  down  to  this  day,  are  based  on  posses- 
sion in  common  of  the  land,  on  the  blending  of  agriculture  and 
handicrafts,  and  on  an  unalterable  division  of  labour,  which 
serves,  whenever  a  new  community  is  started,  as  a  plan  and 
scheme  ready  cut  and  dried.  Occupying  areas  of  from  100  up 
to  several  thousand  acres,  each  forms  a  compact  whole  pro- 
ducing all  it  requires.     The  chief  part  of   the  products   is 

1  "  On  peut  .  .  etablir  en  regie  ginferale,  que  moins  I'autoritd  preside  a  la  division 
du  travail  dans  I'interieur  de  la  societe,  plus  la  division  du  travail  se  developpe  dans 
I'interieur  de  I'atelier,  et  plus  elle  y  est  soumise  k  I'autorite  d'un  seul.  Ainsi 
l'atitorit6  dans  I'atelier  et  celle  dans  la  societe,  par  rapport  a  la  division  du  travail, 
sont  en  raison  inverse  I'une  de  I'autre."    (Karl  Marx,  "  Misere,"  &c.,  pp.  130-131.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture.         3  5 1 

destined  for  direct  use  by  the  community  itself,  and  does  not 
take  the  form  of  a  commodity.  Hence,  production  here  is 
independent  of  that  division  of  labour  brought  about,  in  Indian 
societjT-  as  a  whole,  by  means  of  the  exchange  of  commodities. 
It  is  the  surplus  alone  that  becomes  a  commodity,  and  a  portion 
of  even  that,  not  until  it  has  reached  the  hands  of  the  State, 
into  whose  hands  from  time  immemorial  a  certain  quantity  of 
these  products  has  found  its  way  in  the  shape  of  rent  in  kind. 
The  constitution  of  these  communities  varies  in  different  parts 
of  India.  In  those  of  the  simplest  form,  the  land  is  tilled  in 
common,  and  the  produce  divided  among  the  members.  At 
the  same  time,  spinning  and  weaving  are  carried  on  in  each 
family  as  subsidiary  industries.  Side  by  side  with  the  masses 
thus  occupied  with  one  and  the  same  work,  we  find  the  "  chief 
inhabitant,"  who  is  judge,  police,  and  tax-gatherer  in  one  ;  the 
book-keeper  who  keeps  the  accounts  of  the  tillage  and  registers 
everything  relating  thereto  ;  another  official,  who  prosecutes 
criminals,  protects  strangers  travelling  through,  and  escorts 
them  to  the  next  village  ;  the  boundary  man,  who  guards  the 
boundaries  against  neighbouring  communities  ;  the  water- 
overseer,  who  distributes  the  water  from  the  common  tanks 
for  irrigation ;  the  Brahmin,  who  conducts  the  religious 
services ;  the  schoolmaster,  who  on  the  sand  teaches  the 
children  reading  and  writing  ;  the  calendar-Brahmin,  or  astro- 
loger, who  makes  known  the  lucky  or  unlucky  days  for  seed- 
time and  harvest,  and  for  every  other  kind  of  agricultural 
work ;  a  smith  and  a  carpenter,  who  make  and  repair  all  the 
agricultural  implements  ;  the  potter,  who  makes  all  the  pottery 
of  the  village ;  the  barber,  the  washerman,  who  washes  clothes, 
the  silversmith,  here  and  there  the  poet,  who  in  some  com- 
munities replaces  the  silversmith,  in  others  the  schoolmaster. 
Tliis  dozen  of  individuals  is  maintained  at  the  expense  of  the 
whole  community.  If  the  population  increases,  a  new  com- 
munity is  founded,  on  the  pattern  of  the  old  one,  on  unoccupied 
land.  The  whole  mechanism  discloses  a  systematic  division  of 
labour ;  but  a  division  like  that  in  manufactures  is  impossible, 
since  the  smith  and  the  carpenter,  &;c.,  find  an  unchanging 
market,  and  at  the  most  there  occur,  according  to  the  sizes  of 


352  Capitalist  Production, 

the  villages,  two  or  three  of  each,  instead  of  one/  The  law 
that  regulates  the  division  of  labour  in  the  community  acts 
with  the  irresistible  authority  of  a  law  of  Nature,  at  the  same 
time  that  each  individual  artificer,  the  smith,  the  carpenter, 
and  so  on,  conducts  in  his  workshop  all  the  operations  of  his 
handicraft  in  the  traditional  way,  but  independently,  and 
without  recognizing  any  authority  over  him.  The  simplicit}^ 
of  the  organisation  for  production  in  these  self-sufficing  com- 
munities that  constantly  reproduce  themselves  in  the  same 
form,  and  when  accidentally  destroyed,  spring  up  again  on  the 
spot  and  with  the  same  name^ — this  simplicity  supplies  the 
key  to  the  secret  of  the  unchangeableness  of  Asiatic  societies, 
an  unchangeableness  in  such  striking  contrast  with  the  con- 
stant dissolution  and  refounding  of  Asiatic  States,  and  the 
never-ceasing  changes  of  dynasty.  The  structure  of  the 
economical  elements  of  society  remains  untouched  by  the 
storm-clouds  of  the  political  sky. 

The  rules  of  the  guilds,  as  I  have  said  before,  by  limiting 
most  strictly  the  number  of  apprentices  and  journeymen  that  a 
single  master  could  employ,  prevented  him  from  becoming  a 
capitalist.  Moreover,  he  could  not  employ  his  journeymen  in 
any  other  handicraft  than  the  one  in  which  he  was  a  master. 
The  guilds  zealously  repelled  every  encroachment  by  the  capital 
of  merchants,  the  only  form  of  free  capital  with  which  they 
came  in  contact.  A  merchant  could  buy  every  kind  of  com- 
modity, but  labour  as  a  commodity  he  could  not  buy.  Ho 
existed  only  on  sufferance,  as  a  dealer  in  the  products  of  the 
handicrafts.  If  circumstances  called  for  a  further  division  of 
labour,  the  existing  guilds  split  themselves  up  into  varieties,  or 

1  Lieut. -Col.  Mark  Wilks  :  "Historical  Sketches  of  the  South  of  India."  Lond., 
1810-17,  V.  I.,  pp.  118-20.  A  good  description  of  the  various  forms  of  the  Indian 
communities  is  to  be  found  in  George  Campbell's  "Modern  India."    Lond.,  1852. 

3  "Under  this  simple  form  .  .  .  the  inhabitants  of  the  country  have  lived  from 
time  immemorial.  The  boundaries  of  the  villages  have  been  but  seldom  altered  ;  and 
though  the  villages  themselves  have  been  sometimes  injured,  and  even  desolated  by 
war,  famine,  and  disease,  the  same  name,  the  same  limits,  the  same  interests,  and 
even  the  same  families,  have  continued  for  ages.  The  inhabitants  give  themselves 
no  trouble  about  the  breaking  up  and  division  of  kingdoms  ;  while  the  village  remains 
entire,  they  care  not  to  what  power  it  is  transferred,  or  to  what  sovereign  it  devolves ; 
its  internal  economy  remains  unchanged."  (Th.  Stamford  Raffles,  late  Lieut.  Gov. 
of  Java :  "The  History  of  Java."    Lond.,  1817,  Vol.  I.,  p.  285.) 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,         353 

founded  new  guilds  by  tlie  side  of  the  old  ones ;  all  this,  how- 
ever, without  concentrating  various  handicrafts  in  a  single 
workshop.  Hence,  the  guild  organization,  however  much  it 
may  have  contributed  by  separating,  isolating,  and  perfecting 
the  handicrafts,  to  create  the  material  conditions  for  the  exist- 
ence of  manufacture,  excluded  division  of  labour  in  the 
workshop.  On  the  whole,  the  labourer  and  his  means  of  pro- 
duction remained  closely  united,  like  the  snail  with  its  shell, 
and  thus  there  was  wanting  the  principal  basis  of  manufacture, 
the  separation  of  the  labourer  from  his  means  of  production, 
and  the  conversion  of  these  means  into  capital. 

While  division  of  labour  in  society  at  large,  whether  such 
division  be  brought  about  or  not  by  exchange  of  commodities, 
is  common  to  economical  formations  of  society  the  most  diverse, 
division  of  labour  in  the  workshop,  as  practised  by  manufacture, 
is  a  special  creation  of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production 
alone. 


SECTION  O. — THE  CAPITALISTIC  CHARACTER  OF  MANUFACTURE, 

An  increased  number  of  labourers  under  the  control  of  one 
capitalist  is  the  natural  starting-point,  as  well  of  co-operation 
generally,  as  of  manufacture  in  particular.  But  the  division  of 
labour  in  manufacture  makes  this  increase  in  the  number  of 
workmen  a  technical  necessity.  The  minimum  number  that 
any  given  capitalist  is  bound  to  employ  is  here  prescribed  by 
the  previously  established  division  of  labour.  On  the  other 
hand,  the  advantages  of  further  division  are  obtainable  only 
by  adding  to  the  number  of  workmen,  and  this  can  be  done 
only  by  adding  multiples  of  the  various  detail  groups.  But 
an  increase  in  the  variable  component  of  the  capital  employed 
necessitates  an  increase  in  its  constant  component,  too,  in  the 
workshops,  implements,  &c.,  and,  in  particular,  in  the  raw 
ma;terial,  the  call  for  which  grows  quicker  than  the  number  of 
workmen.  The  quantity  of  it  consumed  in  a  given  time,  by  a 
given  amount  of  labour,  increases  in  the  same  ratio  as  does  the 
productive  power  of  that  labour  in  consequence  of  its  division. 
Hence,  it  is  a  law,  based  on  the  very  nature  of  manufacture, 


354  Capitalist  Production. 

that  the  minimum  amount  of  capital,  which  is  bound  to  be  in 
the  hands  of  each  capitalist,  must  keep  increasing ;  in  other 
words,  that  the  transformation  into  capital  of  the  social  means 
of  production  and  subsistence  must  keep  extending.^ 

In  manufacture,  as  well  as  in  simple  co-operation,  the  collec- 
tive working  organism  is  a  form  of  existence  of  capital.  The 
mechanism  that  is  made  up  of  numerous  individual  detail 
labourers  belongs  to  the  capitalist.  Hence,  the  productive 
power  resulting  from  a  combination  of  labours  appears  to  be 
the  productive  power  of  capital.  Manufacture  proper  not  only 
subjects  the  previously  independent  workman  to  the  discipline 
and  command  of  capital,  but,  in  addition,  creates  a  hierarchic 
gradation  of  the  workmen  themselves.  While  simple  co-opera- 
tion leaves  the  mode  of  working  by  the  individual  for  the  most 
part  unchanged,  manufacture  thoroughly  revolutionises  it,  and 
seizes  labour-power  by  its  very  roots.  It  converts  the  labourer 
into  a  crippled  monstrosity,  by  forcing  his  detail  dexterity 
at  the  expense  of  a  world  of  productive  capabilities  and  in- 
stincts ;  just  as  in  the  States  of  La  Plata  they  butcher  a  whole 
beast  for  the  sake  of  his  hide  or  his  tallow.  Not  only  is  the 
detail  work  distributed  to  the  different  individuals,  but  the  in- 
dividual himself  is  made  the  automatic  motor  of  a  fractional 
operation,^  and  the  absurd  fable  of  Menenius  Agrippa,  which 
makes  man  a  mere  fragment  of  his  own  body,  becomes 
realised.^  If,  at  first,  the  workman  sells  his  labour-power  to 
capital,  because  the  material  means  of  producing  a  commodity 

1  "  It  is  not  sufficient  that  the  capital "  (the  writer  should  have  said  the  necessary- 
means  of  subsistence  and  of  production)  "required  for  the  sub-division  of  handi- 
crafts should  be  in  readiness  in  the  society  :  it  must  also  be  accumulated  in  the  hands 
of  the  employers  in  sufficiently  large  quantities  to  enable  them  to  conduct  their 
operations  on  a  large  scale.  .  .  .  The  more  the  division  increases,  the  more  does  the 
constant  employment  of  a  given  number  of  labourers  require  a  greater  outlay  of  capital 
in  tools,  raw  material,  &c."  (Storch  :  Cours  d'Econ.  Polit.  Paris  Ed.,  t.  I.,  pp.  250, 
251.)  "  La  concentration  des  instruments  de  production  et  la  division  du  travail  sont 
aussi  inseparables  I'une  de  I'autre  que  le  sont,  dans  le  regime  politique,  la  concentra- 
tion des  pouvoirs  publics  et  la  division  des  inter^ts  prives."  (Karl  Marx.  1.  c, 
p.  134.) 

2  Dugald  Stewart  calls  manufacturing  labourers  "living  automatons  .  .  .  employed 
in  the  details  of  the  work."    (1.  c,  p.  318.) 

3  In  corals,  each  individual  is,  in  fact,  the  stomach  of  the  whole  group  ;  but  it  sup- 
plies the  group  with  nourishment,  instead  of,  like  the  Roman  patrician,  withdraw- 
ing it. 


Division  of  Labour  and  Mamtfacture,         355 

fail  him,  now  his  very  labour-power  refuses  its  services  unlesc 
it  has  been  sold  to  capital.  Its  functions  can  be  exercised 
only  in  an  environment  that  exists  in  the  workshop  of  the 
capitalist  after  the  sale.  By  nature  unfitted  to  make  anything 
independently,  the  manufacturing  labourer  developes  produc- 
tive activity  as  a  mere  appendage  of  the  capitalist's  workshop.^ 
As  the  chosen  people  bore  in  their  features  the  sign  manual  of 
Jehovah,  so  division  of  labour  brands  the  manufacturing  work- 
man as  the  property  of  capital. 

The  knowledge,  the  judgment,  and  the  will,  which,  though 
in  ever  so  small  a  degree,  are  practised  by  the  independent 
peasant  or  handicraftsman,  in  the  same  way  as  the  savage 
makes  the  whole  art  of  war  consist  in  the  exercise  of  his  per- 
sonal cunning — these  faculties  are  now  required  only  for  the 
workshop  as  a  whole.  Intelligence  in  production  expands  in 
one  direction,  because  it  vanishes  in  many  others.  What  is 
lost  by  the  detail  labourers,  is  concentrated  in  the  capital  that 
employs  them.^  It  is  a  result  of  the  division  of  labour  in 
manufactures,  that  the  labourer  is  brought  face  to  face  with 
the  intellectual  potencies  of  the  material  process  of  production, 
as  the  property  of  another,  and  as  a  ruling  power.  This  sepa- 
ration begins  in  simple  co-operation,  where  the  capitalist  re- 
presents to  the  single  workman,  the  oneness  and  the  will  of 
the  associated  labour.  It  is  developed  in  manufacture  which 
cuts  down  the  labourer  into  a  detail  labourer.  It  is  com- 
pleted in  modern  industry,  which  makes  science  a  productive 
force  distinct  from  labour  and  presses  it  into  the  service  of 
capital.^ 

1  ' '  L'ouvrier  qui  porte  dans  ses  bras  tout  un  metier,  peut  aller  partout  exercer  son 
industrie  et  trouver  des  raoyens  de  subsister :  I'autre  (the  manufacturing  labourer) 
n'est  qu'un  accessoire  qui,  separd  de  ses  confreres,  n'a  plus  ni  capacity,  ni  independ- 
ance,  et  qui  se  trouve  force  d'accepter  la  loi  qu'on  juge  h.  propos  de  lui  imposer." 
(Storch.     1.  c.     Petersb.  edit.,  1815,  t.  I.,  p.  204.) 

2  A.  Ferguson,  1.  c,  p.  281 :  "  The  former  may  have  gained  what  the  other  has 
lost." 

3  «'  The  man  of  knowledge  and  the  productive  labourer  come  to  be  widely  divided 
from  each  other,  and  knowledge,  instead  of  remaining  the  handmaid  of  labour  in  the 
hand  of  the  labourer  to  increase  his  productive  powers  .  .  .  has  almost  everywhere 
arrayed  itself  against  labour  ....  systematically  deluding  and  leading  them  (the 
labourers)  astray  in  order  to  render  their  muscular  powers  entirely  mechanical  and 
obedient."  (W.  Thompson:  "An  Inquiry  into  the  Principles  of  the  Distribution  of 
Wealth.    London,  1824,"  p.  274.) 


35^  Capitalist  Production. 

In  manufacture,  in  order  to  make  the  collective  labourer, 
and  through  him  capital,  rich  in  social  productive  power,  each 
labourer  must  be  made  poor  in  individual  productive  powers. 
"  Ignorance  is  the  mother  of  industry  as  well  as  of  superstition. 
Reflection  and  fancy  are  subject  to  err ;  but  a  habit  of  moving 
the  hand  or  the  foot  is  independent  of  either.  Manufactures, 
accordingly,  prosper  most  where  the  mind  is  least  consulted, 
and  where  the  workshop  may  ...  be  considered  as  an  engine, 
the  parts  of  which  are  men."  ^  As  a  matter  of  fact,  some 
few  manufacturers  in  the  middle  of  the  18th  century  preferred, 
for  certain  operations  that  were  trade  secrets,  to  employ  half- 
'diotic  persons.^ 

"  The  understandings  of  the  greater  part  of  men,"  says  Adam 
Smith,  "  are  necessarily  formed  by  their  ordinary  employments. 
The  man  whose  whole  life  is  spent  in  performing  a  few  simple 
operations  .  .  .  has  no  occasion  to  exert  his  understanding. 
....  He  generally  becomes  as  stupid  and  ignorant  as  it  is 
possijDle  for  a  human  creature  to  become."  After  describing 
the  stupidity  of  the  detail  labourer  he  goes  on :  "  The  uni- 
formity of  his  stationary  life  naturally  corrupts  the  courage  of 

his  mind It  corrupts  even  the  activity  of  his  body  and 

renders  him  incapable  of  exerting  his  strength  with  vigour  and 
perseverance  in  any  other  employments  than  that  to  which 
he  has  been  bred.  His  dexterity  at  his  own  particular  trade 
seems  in  this  manner  to  be  acquired  at  the  expense  of  his  in- 
tellectual, social,  and  martial  virtues.  But  in  every  improved 
and  civilised  society,  this  is  the  state  into  which  the  labouring 
poor,  that  is,  the  great  body  of  the  people,  must  necessarily 
fall."^     For  preventing  the  complete  deterioration  of  the  great 

1  A.  Ferguson,  1.  c,  p.  280. 

2  J.  D.  Tuckett :  "  A  History  of  the  Past  and  Present  State  of  the  Labouring  Popu- 
lation."   Lond.,  1846. 

3  A.  Smith :  Wealth  of  Nations,  Bk.  V.,  ch.  I.,  art.  II.  Being  a  j)upil  of  A.  Fer- 
guson who  showed  the  disadvantageous  effects  of  division  of  labour,  Adam  Smith 
was  perfectly  clear  on  this  point.  In  the  introduction  to  his  work,  where  he  ex  pro- 
fesso  praises  division  of  labour,  he  indicates  only  in  a  cui'sory  manner  that  it  is  the 
source  of  social  inequalities.  It  is  not  till  the  5th  Book,  on  the  Revenue  of  the  State, 
that  he  reproduces  Ferguson.  In  my  "  Misere  de  la  Philosophie,"  I  have  sufficiently 
explained  the  historical  connection  between  Ferguson,  A.  Smith,  Lemontey,  and  Say, 
as  regards  their  criticisms  of  Division  of  Labour,  and  have  shown,  for  the  first  time, 


Division  of  Labour  and  Manufacture,        357 

mass  of  the  people  by  division  of  labour,  A.  Smith  recommends 
education  of  the  people  by  the  State,  but  prudently,  and  in 
homoeopathic  doses.  G.  Garnier,  his  French  translator  and 
commentator,  who,  under  the  first  French  Empire,  quite  natu- 
rally developed  into  a  senator,  quite  as  naturally  opposes  him 
on  this  point.  Education  of  the  masses,  he  urges,  violates  the 
first  law  of  the  division  of  labour,  and  with  it  "  our  whole 
social  system  would  be  proscribed."  "  Like  all  other  divisions 
of  labour,"  he  says,  "  that  between  hand  labour  and  head 
labour^  is  more  pronounced  and  decided  in  proportion  as  society 
(he  rightly  uses  this  word,  for  capital,  landed  property  and 
their  State)  becomes  richer.  This  division  of  labour,  like  every 
other,  is  an  effect  of  past,  and  a  cause  of  future  progress  .... 
ought  the  government  then  to  work  in  opposition  to  this 
division  of  labour,  and  to  hinder  its  natural  course  ?  Ought  it 
to  expend  a  part  of  the  public  money  in  the  attempt  to  con- 
found and  blend  together  two  classes  of  labour,  which  are 
striving  after  division  and  separation  ? "  ^ 

Some  crippling  of  body  and  mind  is  inseparable  even  from 
division  of  labour  in  society  as  a  whole.  Since,  however,  manu- 
facture carries  this  social  separation  of  branches  of  labour  much 
further,  and  also,  by  its  peculiar  division,  attacks  the  individual 
at  the  very  roots  of  his  life,  it  is  the  first  to  afford  the  materials 
for,  and  to  give  a  start  to,  industrial  pathology.^ 

"  To  subdivide  a  man  is  to  execute  him,  if  he  deserves  the 

that  Division  of  Labour  as  practised  in  manufactures,  is  a  specific  form  of  the  capi- 
talist mode  of  production. 

1  Ferguson  had  already  said,  1.  c.  p.  281 :  "And  thinking  itself,  in  this  age  of 
separations,  may  become  a  peculiar  craft." 

2  G.  Garnier,  vol.  V.  of  his  translation  of  A.  Smith,  pp.  4-5. 

8  Ramazzini,  professor  of  practical  medicine  at  Padua,  published  in  1713  his  work 
"  De  morbis  artificum,"  which  was  translated  into  French  1781,  reprinted  1841  in  the 
"  Encyclopedie  des  Sciences  Medicales.  7"^®  Dis.  Auteurs  Classiques."  The  period 
of  Modern  Mechanical  Industry  has,  of  course,  very  much  enlarged  his  catalogue 
of  labour's  diseases.  See  "  Hygidne  physique  et  morale  de  I'ouvrier  dans  les  grandes 
villes  en  general  et  dans  la  ville  de  Lyon  en  particulier.  Par  le  Dr.  A.  L.  Fonterel, 
Paris,  1858,"  and  "  Die  Krankheiten,  welche  verschiednen  Standen,  Altern  und 
Geschlechtern  eigenthiimlich  sind.  6  Vols.  Ulm,  1860,"  and  others.  la  1854  the 
Society  of  Arts  appointed  a  Commission  of  Inquiry  into  industrial  pathology.  Th« 
list  of  documents  collected  by  this  commission  is  to  be  seen  in  the  catalogue  of  the 
"Twickenham  Economic  Museum."  Very  important  are  the  oflBcial  "  Eeports  on 
Public  Health."  See  also  Eduard  Beich,  M.D.  "Ueber  die  Entartung  des  Men- 
Bchen,"  Erlangen,  1868. 


358  Capitalist  Production, 

sentence,  to  assassinate  liim  if  he  does  not.  .  .  .  The  sub- 
division of  labour  is  the  assassination  of  a  people."^ 

Co-operation  based  on  division  of  labour,  in  other  words, 
manufacture,  commences  as  a  spontaneous  formation.  So  soon 
as  it  attains  some  consistence  and  extension,  it  becomes  the  re- 
cognised methodical  and  systematic  form  of  capitalist  produc- 
tion. History  shows  how  the  division  of  labour  peculiar  to 
manufacture,  strictly  so  called,  acquires  the  best  adapted  form 
at  first  by  experience,  as  it  were  behind  the  backs  of  the  actors, 
and  then,  like  the  guild  handicrafts,  strives  to  hold  fast  that 
form  when  once  found,  and  here  and  there  succeeds  in  keeping 
it  for  centuries.  Any  alteration  in  this  form,  except  in  trivial 
matters,  is  solely  owing  to  a  revolution  in  the  instruments  of 
labour.  Modern  manufacture  wherever  it  arises — I  do  not  here 
allude  to  modern  industry  based  on  machinery — either  finds 
the  disjecta  membra  poetse  ready  to  hand,  and  only  waiting  to 
be  collected  together,  as  is  the  case  in  the  manufacture  of 
clothes  in  large  towns,  or  it  can  easily  apply  the  principle  of 
division,  simply  by  exclusively  assigning  the  various  operations 
of  a  handicraft  (such  as  bookbinding)  to  particular  men.  In 
such  cases,  a  week's  experience  is  enough  to  determine  the  pro- 
portion between  the  numbers  of  the  hands  necessary  for  the 
various  functions.^ 

By  decomposition  of  handicrafts,  by  specialisation  of  the  in- 
struments of  labour,  by  the  formation  of  detail  labourers,  and 
by  grouping  and  combining  the  latter  into  a  single  mechanism, 
division  of  labour  in  manufacture  creates  a  qualitative  grada- 
tion, and  a  quantitative  proportion  in  the  social  process  of 
production ;  it  consequently  creates  a  definite  organisation  of 
the  labour  of  society,  and  thereby  developes  at  the  same  time 

1  (D.  Urquhart :  Familiar  Words.  Lond.,  1855,  p.  119.)  Hegel  held  very  heretical 
views  on  division  of  labour.  In  his  Eechtsphilosophie  he  says  :  "  By  well  educated 
men  we  understand  in  the  first  instance,  those  who  can  do  everything  that  others 
do." 

2  The  simple  belief  in  the  inventive  genius  exercised  a  priori  by  the  individual 
capitalist  in  division  of  labour,  exists  now-a  days  only  among  German  professors,  of 
the  stamp  of  Herr  Roscher,  who,  to  recomj^ense  the  capitalist  from  whose  Jovian 
head  division  of  labour  sprang  ready  formed,  dedicates  to  him  *'  various  wages " 
(diverse  Arbeitslohne).  The  more  or  less  extensive  application  of  division  of  labour 
depends  on  length  of  purse,  not  on  greatness  of  genius. 


Division  of  Labour  and  Mamtfacture,       359 

new  productive  forces  in  the  society.  In  its  specific  capitalist 
form — and  under  the  given  conditions,  it  could  take  no  other 
form  than  a  capitalistic  one — manufacture  is  but  a  particular 
method  of  begetting  relative  surplus-value,  or  of  augmenting 
at  the  expense  of  the  labourer  the  self-expansion  of  capital — 
usually  called  social  wealth,  "  Wealth  of  Nations,"  &ic.  It  in- 
creases the  social  productive  power  of  labour,  not  only  for  the 
benefit  of  the  capitalist  instead  of  for  that  of  the  labourer,  but 
it  does  this  by  crippling  the  individual  labourers.  It  creates 
new  conditions  for  the  lordship  of  capital  over  labour.  If, 
therefore,  on  the  one  hand,  it  presents  itself  historically  as  a 
progress  and  as  a  necessary  phase  in  the  economic  develop- 
ment of  society,  on  the  other  hand  it  is  a  refined  and  civilised 
method  of  exploitation. 

Political  economy,  which  as  an  independent  science,  first 
sprang  into  being  during  the  period  of  manufacture,  views 
the  social  division  of  labour  only  from  the  standpoint  of 
manufacture,^  and  sees  in  it  only  the  means  of  producing  more 
commodities  with  a  given  quantity  of  labour,  and,  conse- 
quently, of  cheapening  commodities  and  hurrying  on  the 
accumulation  of  capital.  In  most  striking  contrast  with  this 
accentuation  of  quantity  and  exchange-value,  is  the  attitude 
of  the  writers  of  classical  antiquity,  who  hold  exclusively  by 
quality  and  use-value.^  In  consequence  of  the  separation  of 
the  social  branches  of  production,  commodities  are  better 
made,  the  various  bents  and  talents  of  men  select  a  suitable 

1  The  older  writers,  like  Petty  and  the  anonymous  author  of  "Advantages  of  the 
East  India  Trade,"  bring  out  the  capitalist  character  of  division  of  labour  as  applied 
in  manufacture  more  than  A.  Smith  does. 

2  Amongst  the  moderns  may  be  excepted  a  few  writers  of  the  18th  century,  like 
Beccaria  and  James  Harris,  who  with  regard  to  division  of  labour  almost  entirely 
follow  the  ancients.  Thus,  Beccaria :  "  Ciascuno  prova  coll'  esperienza,  die  applicando 
la  hiano  e  I'ingegno  sempre  alio  stesso  genere  di  opere  e  di  produtte,  egli  piii  facili, 
piii  abbondanti  e  migliori  ne  traca  lisultati,  di  quello  che  se  ciascuno  isolatamente  le 
cose  tutte  a  se  necessarie  soltanto  facesse.  .  .  .  Dividendosi  in  tal  maniera  per  la 
comune  e  privata  utilitjl  gli  uomini  in  varie  classi  e  condizioni."  (Cesare  Beccaria : 
"Elemonti  di  Econ.  Pubblica,"  ed.  Custodi,  Parte  Moderna,  t.  xi.,  p.  28.)  James 
Harris,  afterwards  Earl  of  Malmesbury,  celebrated  for  the  ' '  Diaries  "  of  his  embassy 
at  St.  Petersburg,  says  in  a  note  to  his  "  Dialogue  Concerning  Happiness,"  Lond., 
1741, reprinted  afterwards  in  "  Three  Treatises,  &c.,  3  Ed.,  Lond.,  1772  :"  "The  whole 
argument  to  prove  society  natural  {i.e.,  by  division  of  employments)  ...  is  taken 
from  the  second  book  of  Plato's  Kepublic." 


360  Capitalist  Production. 

field/  and  without  some  restraint  no  important  results  can  be 
obtained  anywhere.^  Hence  both  product  and  producer  are 
improved  by  division  of  labour.  If  the  growth  of  the  quantity 
produced  is  occasionally  mentioned,  this  is  only  done  with 
reference  to  the  greater  abundance  of  use- values.  There  is  not 
a  word  alluding  to  exchange-value  or  to  the  cheapening  of 
commodities.  This  aspect,  from  the  standpoint  of  use-value 
alone,  is  taken  as  well  by  Plato,^  who  treats  division  of  labour 
as  the  foundation  on  which  the  division  of  society  into  classes 
is  based,  as  by  Xenophon/  who  with  characteristic  bourgeois 

1  Thus,  in  the  Odyssey  xiv, ,  228,  ""AXXo?  yhp  tHWoktiv  a.vyif  WiTipTSTKi  ^pyor,," 
and  Archilochus  in  Sextus  Erapiricus,  "  uWos  Sixxu  It"  ^pyu  xap^inv  lahirai." 

2  "riaxx'  riTlffTciTe  ^pyet^  xeexu;  VriTtsTaro  -rcivTa."  Every  Athenian  considered  him- 
self superior  as  a  producer  of  commodities  to  a  Spartan  ;  for  the  latter  in  time  of 
war  had  men  enough  at  his  disposal  but  could  not  command  money,  as  Thucydides 
makes  Pericles  say  in  the  speech  inciting  the  Athenians  to  the  Peloponnesian  war  : 

(Tet/f^aa-i  rt  eToifiorspot  ol  airrovpyoX  rut  av^paTu*  ij  ^prifjt,a<rt  uroXtf.iiv,'*  (Thuc  :  1.  I.  C. 
41.)  Nevertheless,  even  with  regard  to  material  production,  airapKUK^  as  opposed 
to  division  of  labour  remained  their  ideal,  •'  trap*  Zv  yup  to  iS,  ^apei  toutuv  xal  to 
ff.vTKpxii.'^  It  should  be  mentioned  here  that  at  the  date  of  the  fall  of  the  30  Tyrants 
there  were  still  not  5000  Athenians  without  landed  property. 

3  With  Plato,  division  of  labour  within  the  community  is  a  development  from  the 
multifarious  requirements,  and  the  limited  caj)acities  of  individuals.  The  main  point 
with  him  is,  that  the  labourer  must  adapt  himself  to  the  work,  not  the  work  to  the 
labourer ;  which  latter  is  unavoidable,  if  he  carries  on  several  trades  at  once,  thus 
making  one  or  the  other  of  them  subordinate.  "  Oi)  yap  tfiXu  to  ■rparTOfzivov  tjjv  toO 
trp&TTovTOi  (Tp^oXriv  'TiptiiUiiv^  aXA.*  avdyxT}  rov  vrpaTTovrx  tm  <rpaTTOfit,i>iio  l<raxo\ouhiv  fjcii 
Iv  'ffapipyou  fiipti. — *Avdyxti, — 'Ex  ^r]  toutuv  ^Xi'iu  Ti  ixoLffra.  ylyviTat  xal  xdXXtov  xal 
petov,  oTuv  ili  iv  xetra  <puffiv  xal  iv  xaipZ  tr^oXhv  Tuv  S.k'Kuv  &yuv  TpexTTi^^^  (Rep.  1.  2.  Ed. 
Baiter,  Orelli,  &c).  So  in  Thucydides  1.  c.  c,  42  :  "  Seafaring  is  an  art  like  any 
other,  and  cannot,  as  circumstances  require,  be  carried  on  as  a  subsidiary  occupation ; 
nay,  other  subsidiary  occupations  cannot  be  carried  on  alongside  of  this  one."  If  the 
work,  says  Plato,  has  to  wait  for  the  labourer,  the  critical  point  in  the  process  is 
missed  and  the  article  spoiled,  'ipyou  xaipov  ^ioWvtoh.*'  The  same  Platonic  idea  is 
found  recurring  in  the  protest  of  the  English  bleachers  against  the  clause  in  the 
Factory  Act  that  provides  fixed  meal  times  for  all  operatives.  Their  business  cannot 
wait  the  convenience  of  the  workmen,  for  *'  in  the  various  operations  of  singeing, 
washing,  bleaching,  mangling,  calendering,  and  dyeing,  none  of  them  can  be  stopped 
at  a  given  moment  without  risk  of  damage  ....  to  enforce  the  same  dinner  hour 
for  all  the  work-people  might  occasionally  subject  valuable  goods  to  the  risk  of  danger 
by  incomplete  operations."    Le  platonisme  ou  va-t-il  se  nicher  ! 

4  Xenophon  says,  it  is  not  only  an  honour  to  receive  food  from  the  table  of  the  King 
of  Persia,  but  such  food  is  much  more  tasty  than  other  food.  "And  there  is  nothing 
wonderful  in  this,  for  as  the  other  arts  are  brought  to  special  perfection  in  the  great 
towns,  so  the  royal  food  is  prepared  in  a  special  way.  For  in  the  small  towns  the 
same  man  makes  bedsteads,  doors,  ploughs,  and  tables :  often,  too,  he  builds  houses 
into  the  bargain,  and  is  quite  content  if  he  finds  custom  sufficient  for  his  sustenance. 


Division  of  Labottr  and  Manufacture.       361 

instinct,  approaches  more  nearly  to  division  of  labour  within 
the  workshop.  Plato's  Republic,  in  so  far  as  division  of  labour 
is  treated  in  it,  as  the  formative  principle  of  the  State,  is 
merely  the  Athenian  idealisation  of  the  Egyptian  system  of 
castes,  Egypt  having  served  as  the  model  of  an  industrial 
country  to  many  of  his  contemporaries  also,  amongst  others  to 
Isocrates,^  and  it  continued  to  have  this  importance  to  the 
Greeks  of  the  Roman  Empire.^ 

During  the  manufacturing  period  proper,  i.e.,  the  period 
during  which  manufacture  is  the  predominant  form  taken  by 
capitalist  production,  many  obstacles  are  opposed  to  the  full 
development  of  the  peculiar  tendencies  of  manufacture. 
Although  manufacture  creates,  as  we  have  already  seen,  a 
simple  separation  of  the  labourers  into  skilled  and  unskilled, 
simultaneously  with  their  hierarchic  arrangeuient  in  classes, 
yet  the  number  of  the  unskilled  labourers,  owing  to  the  pre- 
ponderating influence  of  the  skilled,  remains  very  limited. 
Although  it  adapts  the  detail  operations  to  the  various  degrees 
of  maturity,  strength,  and  development  of  the  living  instru- 
ments of  labour,  thus  conducing  to  exploitation  of  women  and 
children,  yet  this  tendency  as  a  whole  is  wrecked  on  the  habits 
and  the  resistance   of  the   male    labourers.      Although   the 

It  is  altogether  impossible  for  a  man  who  does  so  many  things  to  do  them  all  well. 
But  in  the  great  towns,  where  each  can  find  many  buyers,  one  trade  is  sufficient  to 
maintain  the  man  who  carries  it  on.  Nay,  there  is  often  not  even  need  of  one  com- 
plete trade,  but  one  man  makes  shoes  for  men,  another  for  women.  Here  and  there 
one  man  gets  a  living  by  sewing,  another  by  cutting  out  shoes  ;  one  does  nothing  but 
cut  out  clothes,  another  nothing  but  sew  the  pieces  together.  It  follows  necessarily 
then,  that  he  who  does  the  simplest  kind  of  work,  undoubtedly  does  it  better  than 
anyone  else.  So  it  is  with  the  art  of  cooking."  (Xen.  Cyrop.  1.  viii.,  c.  2.)  Xeno- 
phon  here  lays  stress  exclusively  upon  the  excellence  to  be  attained  in  use-value, 
although  he  well  knows  that  the  gradations  of  the  division  of  labour  depend  on  the 
extent  of  the  market. 

1  He  (Busiris)  divided  them  all  into  special  castes commanded  that  the 

same  individuals  should  always  carry  on  the  same  trade,  for  he  knew  that  they  who 
change  their  occupations  become  skilled  in  none ;  but  that  those  who  constantly  stick 
to  one  occupation  bring  it  to  the  highest  perfection.  In  truth,  we  shall  also  find  tha; 
in  relation  to  the  arts  and  handicrafts,  they  have  outstripped]their  rivals  more  than  a 
master  does  a  bungler  ;  and  the  contrivances  for  maintaining  the  monarchy  and  the 
other  institutions  of  their  State  are  so  admirable  that  the  most  celebrated  philo- 
sophers who  treat  of  this  subject  praise  the  constitution  of  the  Egyptian  State  above 
all  others.     (Isocrates,  Busiris,  c.  8.) 

2  Of.  Diodorus  Siculus. 


o 


62  Capitalist  Production. 


splitting  up  of  handicrafts  lowers  the  cost  of  forming  the  work- 
man, and  thereby  lowers  his  value,  yet  for  the  more  difficult 
detail  work,  a  longer  apprenticeship  is  necessary,  and,  even 
vvliere  it  would  be  superfluous,  is  jealously  insisted  upon  by 
the  workmen.  In  England,  for  instance,  we  find  the  laws  of 
apprenticeship,  with  their  seven  years'  probation,  in  full  force 
down  to  the  end  of  the  manufacturing  period ;  and  they  are 
not  thrown  on  one  side  till  the  advent  of  Modern  Industry. 
Since  handicraft  skill  is  the  foundation  of  manufacture,  and 
since  the  mechanism  of  manufacture  as  a  whole  possesses  no 
framework,  apart  from  the  labourers  themselves,  capital  is  con- 
stantly compelled  to  wrestle  with  the  insubordination  of  the 
workmen.  "  By  the  infirmity  of  human  nature,"  says  friend 
Ure,  "it  happens  that  the  more  skilful  the  workman,  the  more 
self-willed  and  intractable  he  is  apt  to  become,  and  of  course 
the  less  fit  a  component  of  a  mechanical  system  in  which  .  .  . 
he  may  do  great  damage  to  the  whole."  ^  Hence  throughout 
the  whole  manufacturing  period  there  runs  the  complaint  of 
want  of  discipline  among  the  workmen.^  And  had  we  not  the 
testimony  of  contemporary  writers,  the  simple  facts,  that  during 
the  period  between  the  16th  century  and  the  epoch  of  Modern 
Industry,  capital  failed  to  become  the  master  of  the  whole 
disposable  working-time  of  the  manufacturing  labourers,  that 
manufactures  are  short-lived,  and  change  their  locality  from 
one  country  to  another  with  the  emigrating  or  immigrating 
workmen,  these  facts  would  speak  volumes.  "  Order  must  in 
one  way  or  another  be  established,"  exclaims  in  1770  the  oft- 
cited  author  of  the  "  Essay  on  Trade  and  Commerce."  "  Order," 
re-echoes  Dr.  Andrew  Ure  ^Q  years  later,  "  Order  "  was  wanting 
in  manufacture  based  on  "  the  scholastic  dogma  of  division  of 
labour,"  and  "  Arkwright  created  order." 

At  the  same  time  manufacture  was  unable,  either  to  seize 
upon  the  production  of  society  to  its  full  extent,  or  to  re- 
volutionise that  production  to  its  very  core.  It  towered  u])  as 
an  economical  work  of  art,  on  the  broad  foundation^  of  the  town 

1  Ure,  1.  c,  p.  20. 

2  This  is  more  the  case  in  England  than  in  France,  and  more  in  France  than  in 
Holland. 


Divisio7i  of  Labour  and  Manufactttre.       363 

handicrafts,  and  of  the  rural  domestic  industries.  At  a  given 
stage  in  its  development,  the  narrow  technical  basis  on  which 
manufacture  rested,  came  into  conflict  with  requirements  of 
production  that  were  created  by  raanufacture  itself. 

One  of  its  most  finished  creations  was  the  workshop  for  the 
production  of  the  instruments  of  labour  themselves,  including 
especially  the  complicated  mechanical  apparatus  then  already 
employed.  A  machine-factory,  says  Ure,  "displayed  the  division 
of  labour  in  manifold  gradations — the  file,  the  drill,  the  lathe, 
having  each  its  different  workman  in  the  order  of  skill."  (p.  21.) 
This  workshop,  the  product  of  the  division  of  labour  in  manufac- 
ture, produced  in  its  turn — machines.  It  is  they  that  sweep  away 
the  handicraftsman's  work  as  the  regulating  principle  of  social 
production.  Thus,  on  the  one  hand,  the  technical  reason  for 
the  life-long  annexation  of  the  workman  to  a  detail  function 
is  removed.  On  the  other  hand,  the  fetters  that  this  same 
principle  laid  on  the  dominion  of  capital,  fall  away. 


H3^ 


'./ 


t 


h 


^  I 


I 


•■i  feVii^fiV 


,  >-\.*>  'lY 


.nN 


.N^'Vt<' 


^^l:)^:^f  S'^Si^l'  ^?:®» 


'i'^>V 


>         < 


V'?'!.^ 


1  \