Skip to main content

Full text of "Consumption benefits of education"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  Of- 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


H 


0/s\  t>  f5 


m 


H 


H 


CO 


CD 

CD 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/consumptionbenef856mcma 


,«.  ypts 


o^y 


EBR 


FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  856 


Consumption  Benefits  of  Education 
Walter  W.  McMahon 


Coiiege  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  sf  Illinois,  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  856 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
March  1982 


Consumption  Benefits  of  Education 


Walter  W.  McMahon,  Professor 
Department  of  Economics 
Department  of  Education 


Abstract 

New  developments  in  the  economic  theory  of  household  production  of 
final  consumption  satisfactions  has  led  to  a  vast  outpouring  of  new 
research  on  the  contribution  made  by  education  to  the  efficiency  of 
production  of  these  final  consumption  satisfactions  during  leisure  time 
hours  within  the  family. 

The  results  of  careful  research  must  hold  constant  the  benefits  of 
education  in  the  form  of  higher  earnings,  so  that  these  are  not  counted 
indirectly  when  measuring  non-monetary  consumption  benefits.   Results  of 
the  studies  surveyed  here  point  to  strong  evidence  that  the  better 
education  of  the  woman  in  a  family  contributes  to  her  own  better  health 
and  the  better  health  of  her  husband  and  children.   There  is  also 
evidence  that  education  contributes  positively  to  the  education  of  the 
children,  to  earning  a  higher  rate  of  return  on  savings,  and  to  more 
efficient  home  management  (e.g.  purchasing  behavior,  tele-banking,  or 
efficient  appliance  repairs).   But  other  studies  find  that  education  is 
counter-productive  in  those  aspects  of  housekeeping  where  the  cognitive 
and  affective  attributes  it  develops  contribute  less  to  productivity  and 
therefore  encourage  substitution  of  time  away  from  activities  such  as 
dishwashing,  mending,  and  the  more  time- intensive  aspects  of  child 
rearing.   This  is  somewhat  analogous  to  the  effects  of  education  on 
productivity  and  on  time  substitution  within  and  among  jobs  in  the 
marketplace. 


Consumption  Benefits  of  Education 

The  consumption  benefits  of  education  are  regarded  here  as  the 
non-monetary  returns  accruing  from  education  to  the  individual  through- 
out the  life  cycle.   As  such,  they  include  not  only  the  non-monetary 
satisfactions  enjoyed  by  the  student  while  in  school,  but  also  the 
contribution  made  by  education  to  the  efficiency  of  household  produc- 
tion of  final  consumer  satisfactions  during  leisure  time  hours  before 
and  after  retirement,  plus  the  contribution  made  by  homemakers  during 
the  non-market  time  spent  in  household  management  and  child  rearing. 

Many  of  these  consumption  benefits  have  been  measured  in  a  vast  out- 
pouring of  recent  research.   This  research  has  largely  followed  the 
lament  by  T.  W.  Schultz  in  surveying  the  earlier  literature  that  "all 
these  studies  omit  the  consumption  value  of  education. . .It  is  a 
serious  omission. . .The  available  estimates  of  earnings  from  education 
in  this  respect  all  underestimate  the  real  value  of  education" 
(Schultz,  1967,  p.  300).   The  most  fruitful  empirical  results  have 
been  achieved  by  use  of  the  theory  of  household  production  as  developed 
primarily  by  Gary  Becker  (1975,  pp.  67-8,  and  1976,  Ch.  7)  and  as  ex- 
tended and  recently  surveyed  by  Robert  Michael  (1972,  1982),  in  an 
excellent  survey  which  the  reader  is  encouraged  to  see.  The  results 
of  recent  research  which  are  summarized  below  find  education  to  make 
positive  contributions  to  many  types  of  non-market  activities  involv- 
ing significant  cognitive  or  education-related  affective  attributes, 
activities  such  as  maintaining  the  health  of  family  members,  earning 
a  higher  rate  of  return  on  savings ,  improving  the  children's  school 
achievement  and  pre-school  IQ,  increasing  the  efficiency  of  household 
purchasing,  and  staying  out  of  jail.   Some  studies  find  education 


-2- 

counterproductive  for  Che  more  mundane  household  (and  workforce)  tasks, 
inducing  time  to  be  shifted  away  from  those  tasks  where  education  con- 
tributes less  to  productivity,  such  as  dishwashing,  mending,  ironing, 
and  the  more  time-intensive  aspects  of  child  rearing — e.g.,  Lemennicier 
(1978)  and  Levy-Garbona  (1978),  analogous  to  similar  counterproductive 
effects  found  for  analogous  time-intensive  tasks  in  the  workplace 
found  by  Rumberger  (1981),  Levin,  and  others. 

The  following  focuses  on  those  studies  that  control  in  some  way 
for  the  purely  market  benefits  of  education  to  avoid  double  counting 
the  satisfactions  secured  through  the  use  of  education  in  the  work- 
place.  This  summary  excludes  non-monetary  satisfactions  on  the  job, 
e.g.,  Duncan  (1976),  since  these  derive  from  the  use  of  market  time. 
The  private  consumption  benefits  from  education  considered  below  ex- 
clude externalities  and  spill-over  benefits  which  accrue  to  the 
society  (or  to  other  jurisdictions)  above  and  beyond  those  that  ac- 
crue to  the  individual — both  are  treated  in  separate  articles.  We 
will  also  focus  on  these  microeconomic  studies  that  test  for  measurable 
non-market  effects — there  is  some  work  on  the  macro  level,  however, 
by  Eisner  (1981),  McMahon  (1981),  and  Kendrick  (1979)  that  expands 
imputed  values  in  the  national  income  and  product  accounts  to  include 
an  imputed  value  for  the  services  of  the  education  of  homemakers  in 
total  consumption  and  hence  in  total  product  and  total  productivity. 

I.   Research  on  Measured  Consumption  Benefits 
Consumption  benefits  of  education  can  be  regarded  as  those  that 
fall  within  the  "new  theory  of  consumer  behavior,"  even  though  most 


-3- 

occur  later  in  Che  life  cycle  and  therefore  can  alternatively  be  viewed 
as  a  non-monetary  return  on  an  investment.   Higher  earnings  are  a  pure 
investment  return,  however,  and  hence  are  considered  separately  under 
investment  returns  and  under  expected  rates  of  return  to  education 
(which  see),  by  Psacharopoulos  (1973),  and  by  McMahon  and  Wagner  (1982)). 
In  considering  consumption  benefits,  those  studies  will  not  be  included 
that  do  not  eliminate  the  benefits  from  education  due  to  higher  earn- 
ings. 

Pure  current  consumption  effects  are  the  current  satisfactions  en- 
joyed when  schooling  itself  is  enjoyable — particularly  at  high  school 
and  college  levels  and  in  leisure-time  courses — plus  current  services 
provided  by  local  schools  to  the  family  such  as  hot  lunches,  community 
center  services,  and  child  care.   Although  these  can  be  observed,  little 
has  been  done  to  measure  them  beyond  one  study  by  Lazear  (1977)  and  as- 
pects of  some  cost-benefit  studies  of  day-care  services  by  Gustafson 
(1978)  and  others.  More  work  on  this  is  needed. 

Health.  There  is  strong  evidence  that  education  contributes  to 
better  health.   Numerous  studies  show  that  education  is  highly  correlated 
with  good  health,  and  highly  significant  work  by  Grossman  (1976)  con- 
siderably refines  this.   He  controls  for  the  individual's  income,  IQ, 
health  status  as  a  teenager,  and  wife's  schooling,  to  find  an  effect  of 
education  on  health  status  by  age  46  that  is  about  40%  as  strong  as  the 
effect  of  education  on  wages.   He  finds  that  the  wife's  schooling  has 
an  even  bigger  positive  effect  on  the  man's  health  than  does  his  own 
schooling.   Those  with  more  education  live  longer;  each  additional 
year  of  schooling  lowers  the  probability  of  death  by  0.4  percentage 


-4- 

points.  Lando  (1975)  finds  less  work  disability,  and  in  a  later  study 
Grossman  (1982),  again  holding  income  and  other  factors  constant,  finds 
that  the  children  of  more  educated  women  tend  to  have  healthier  teeth, 
are  less  likely  to  be  anemic,  and  are  less  likely  to  be  obese.   Al- 
though the  positive  effects  of  schooling  on  the  individual's  own  health, 
of  the  wife's  schooling  on  her  husband's  health,  and  of  the  woman's 
education  on  the  health  of  her  children  are  now  well  documented, 
nobody  yet  has  studied  the  effect  of  the  education  of  the  husband  on 
his  wife's  health. 

Effects  on  Further  Learning.   Leibowitz  (1974),  using  Ben-Porath's 
well  known  model  of  the  household  production  of  human  capital  over 
time,  that  a  mother's  education  and  pre-school  home  investments  in 

A 

children  significantly  raise  the  child's  IQ.   Benson  (1982)  finds  that 
high  SES  families  tend  to  limit  TV  viewing  and  pay  more  attention  to 
whether  or  not  the  child  does  his  homework,  a  factor  positively 
related  to  school  achievement.   The  number  of  years  of  college  planned 
by  white  male  and  by  black  male  college  freshmen  has  been  found  by 
McMahon  (1976,  p.  322),  after  controlling  for  family  income,  ability, 
and  all  financial  aids,  to  be  positively  influenced  by  the  education 
of  the  parents. 

Ben-Porath  neutrality  implies  that  the  young  person's  past  education 
is  productive  in  further  education  as  every  school  admissions  officer 
knows,  but  also  that  this  is  only  at  the  cost  of  its  equal  productivity 
in  the  market.   This  is  not  an  issue  when  considering  the  productivity 
of  education  in  the  home  during  leisure  time  hours  however  (since  in 
this  case  there  are  no  foregone  earnings),  or  as  the  education  of  the 


-5- 

parents  contributes  to  the  further  education  of  the  child  in  exchanges 
within  the  family. 

Returns  on  Savings.   Solomon  (1975)  finds  that  the  level  of  educa- 
tion among  respondents  in  a  survey  of  members  of  the  Consumers  Union, 
after  controlling  for  income  and  occupation,  has  the  strongest  relation 
to  choosing  the  best  inflation  hedge  for  their  savings. 

Consumption  Behavior.   Michael  (1972,  1982)  finds  that  those  con- 
sumers with  higher  levels  of  education  shift  their  spending  patterns 
among  consumption  items,  behaving  as  if  they  have  more  real  income, 
(over  and  above  the  higher  money  earnings  that  they  also  have).  He 
estimates  this  real  income  effect  of  schooling  on  non-market  production 
of  consumption  satisfaction  to  have  an  elasticity  of  .5,  an  effect  about 
60  percent  as  great  as  the  comparable  relation  of  schooling  to  money 
earnings. 

Expected  consumption  benefits  also  appear,  in  preliminary  evidence, 
to  average  50-60%  of  the  monetary  returns  expected  by  students  from 
their  higher  education.   When  5,000  students  were  each  asked  to  appraise 
the  value  of  the  non-monetary,  leisure  time  returns  to  them,  relative 
to  the  expected  monetary  returns,  McMahon  (1974)  finds  that  students 
in  fields  like  music  placed  the  expected  non-monetary  returns  above 
the  expected  monetary  returns,  and  those  in  medicine  and  business 
tended  to  place  them  at  far  less.  McMahon  (1982)  also  finds  that 
expected  earnings  tend  to  have  the  relatively  stronger  influence  on 
most  student  and  family  educational  investment  decisions,  an  influence 
that  is  even  more  pronounced  at  the  more  advanced  levels. 


-6- 

But  within  the  sphere  of  non-market  behavior,  education  is  more 
productive  in  some  household  activities  than  in  others.   Bertrand 
Lemermicier  (1979)  challenges  Michael's  important  simplifying  assump- 
tion that  education  is  technologically  neutral  among  these  activities — 

dJfows 
an  assumption  that  eventually  had  to  be  challenged — which  schooling 

to  affect  the  relative  price  of  time  within  the  household.   He  finds 
that  this  causes  time  to  be  shifted  away  from  those  types  of  activities 
which  are  time-intensive,  so  that  in  these  activities  education  is 
counterproductive.    //e  findj;  for  example,  that  a  very  large  propor- 
tion of  the  time  budgets  of  French  housewives  is  occupied  by  dish- 
washing, and  although  he  agreejwith  the  positive  effects  of  educa- 
tion on  health,  schooling,  and  saving  behavior  which  require  cognitive 
and  affective  skills,  the  overall  shifts  away  from  dishwashing,  mend- 
ing, ironing,  and  analogous  activities  in  the  time  budgets  of  the  more 
educated  French  housewives  leads  him  to  conclude  that  education  is 
counterproductive  in  these  forms  of  household  production.   This  is 
consistent  with  the  now  numerous  research  studies  by  Gustafson  (1978), 
Levy-Garbona  (1978),  Ferber  and  McMahon  (1979),  and  others  documenting 
the  time  shifts  of  the  more  educated   women  in  Sweden,  France.-Jthe 
U.S.,  toward  entry  into  the  labor  force. 

Home  Management .   The  simultaneous  technological  revolution  within 
the  home  however  may  require  even  less  time-intensive  labor  and  in- 
creasing levels  of  education  for  effective  home  management  using  fewer 
hours m     The  rapid  swing  to  dishwashers,  automatic  washing  machines, 
wash  and  wear  clothing,  and  monthly  bill  paying  by  check  require  less 
time  than  the  earlier  methods.   But  they  do  require  knowlege  of  home 


-7- 

repairs  and  repair  management,  plus  some  accounting  skills.   Tele- 
shopping  for  groceries  and  sundries  is  now  in  use  in  217  U.S.  cities, 
tele-bill  paying  and  tele-banking  are  spreading,  and  Apple  computers  are 
now  available  at  increasingly  reasonable  cost  for  managing  household 
energy  use,  adjusting  savings  portfolios,  teaching  the  children,  doing 
the  income  tax,  and  even  life-cycle  planning — -all  requiring  more  (and 
changing)  education  for  their  effective  use. 

There  are  many  studies,  not  all  accompanied  by  adequate  controls 
for  differences  in  money  income,  that  offer  evidence  that  those  with 
more  education  tend  to  adopt  new  products  more  quickly.   Of  those  that 
do  attempt  to  hold  real  income  constant,  Mandell  (1972)  finds  that 
those  with  more  education  adopted  credit  cards  faster,  Michael  (1982) 
reports  on  several  studies  including  his  own  that  indicate  that  more 
educated  women  are  more  likely  to  use  contraception  and  to  have  fewer 
"unwanted"  births;  and  Hettich  (1972)  finds  that  more  educated  women 
are  more  efficient  in  market  search,  with  potential  savings  as  the  re- 
sult of  more  efficient  purchasing  behavior  that  raises  the  estimated 
rate  of  return  to  a  college  education  by  1.5  percentage  points. 
Nobody  yet  has  studied  whether  or  not  persons  with  more  education 
realize  more  of  the  deductions  to  which  they  are  entitled  on  their 
income  tax. 

Affective  Attributes  Created  By  Education,  as  distinguished  from  the 
more  cognitive  attributes,  affect  productivity  in  consumption  in  addi- 
tion to  their  affect  on  earnings. 

The  clearest  measures  are  of  the  comparative  advantage  schooling 
confers  in  the  selection  of  a  desirable  spouse.   Michael  (1982)  develops 


the  point  that  own-schooling  and  the  schooling  of  one's  mate  are  posi- 
tively correlated  by  at  least  .4,  making  education  a  good  investment  in 
securing  a  spouse  whose  earning  capacity  and  presumably  other  attributes 
are  more  desirable.   The  amount  of  college  education  planned  by  students 
is  also  found  to  be  positively  and  significantly  related  to  "finding  a 
spouse  with  college  values"  in  a  study  by  McMahon  (1982b),  who  controls 
for  expected  monetary  returns,  as  well  as  for  financial  aids  and  other 
influences  on  student  decisions.   It  is  interesting  that  the  coefficient 
for  this  expected  non-monetary  return  is  four  times  as  large,  and  the 
t-statistic  is  twice  as  large,  for  men  as  it  is  for  women  students. 
Benham  (1974)  and  Welch  (1974)  find  that  a  wife's  schooling  raises  her 
husband's  annual  earnings  by  about  3.5%. 

Such  affective  returns  from  education  as  meeting  and  conversing  with 
more  interesting  people,  capacities  for  entertaining  guests,  and  com- 
munity service  (although  the  latter  is  an  external  benefit  discussed 
elsewhere)  are  recognized  by  students  and  expected  to  be  positive, 
although  only  meeting  more  interesting  people  was  found  by  McMahon 
(1982b)  to  have  significant  effects  on  student  decisions.   Becker 
(1981,  Ch.  4)  suggests  that  schooling  can  contribute  to  greater  happi- 
ness in  marriage  since  it  facilitates  a  more  nearly  optimal  sorting 
among  mates  in  the  marriage  market.   But  women  with  more  education 
also  are  more  prone  to  divorce,  generating  disutilities  for  the  hus- 
band and  children,  a  fact  that  Becker  (1981,  p.  231)  and  others  have 
usually  associated  with  the  growth  in  women's  earnings  that  lessen  the 
economic  advantages  of  marriage  rather  than  with  education  per  se. 


-9- 

Education  facilitates  readjustment  for  divorced  persons  with  more 
education  who  are  known  to  remarry  more  quickly.   Also  in  the  broader 
role  stressed  by  Schultz  (1975),  it  allows  individuals  to  adapt  more 
easily  to  changes  on  the  job,  disequilibria  in  the  market,  and  new 
technology  in  the  home.   It  also  changes  tastes — from  drag  racing  or 
horse  racing,  for  example,  toward  concerts  and  reading  editorials. 
But  the  net  effects  of  pure  shifts  in  tastes  on  consumer  satisfaction 
cancel  out  to  some  extent.   Rather  than  concentrate  on  taste  shifts, 
the  research  focusing  on  the  effects  on  productivity  in  household 
production  has  been  far  more  fruitful. 

In  summary,  all  that  goes  before  suggests  that  there  are  now  many 
good  studies  offering  evidence  of  positive  consumption  benefits  of  edu- 
cation— benefits  (after  holding  earnings  constant)  to  the  family's 
health,  schooling,  return  on  savings,  purchasing  efficiency,  home  manage- 
ment skills,  and  affective  sources  of  happiness.   Against  this,  the 
counterproductive  effects  relating  to  divorce  and  to  the  time  intensive 
activities  in  the  home  requiring  less  skill  must  be  netted  out.   Beyond 
testing  for  additional  effects,  needed  next  steps  include  extending  the 
work  by  Michael  and  others  using  shadow  prices  to  impute  values  (both 
positive  and  negative)  to  each  of  these  non-monetary  benefits  for  in- 
dividual families,  and  also  for  total  consumption  and  total  product 
at  the  macro  level  in  the  national  income  and  product  accounts.   These 
would  have  to  include  the  value  of  education  in  facilitating  adjust- 
ment to  disequilibria,  whether  they  be  caused  by  market  opportunities, 
divorce,  or  new  technology  within  the  family. 


Walter  W.  McMahon 
University  of  Illinois 


•10- 


Ref erences  and  Further  Reading 


Becker  Gary  S  1975  Human  Capital.   University  of  Chicago  Press, 
Chicago  and  London. 

1976  The  Economic  Approach  to  Human  Behavior.   Univer- 


sity of  Chicago  Press,  Chicago  and  London. 

1981  A  Treatise  on  the  Family.   Harvard  University 


Press,  Cambridge,  Mass.  and  London,  England. 

Benham  Lee   1974   "Benefits  of  Women's  Education  Within  Marriage,"  in 
Economics  of  the  Family,  Theodore  W.  Schultz,  ed. ,  pp.  375-389, 
University  of  Chicago  Press,  Chicago  and  London. 

Benson  Charles  S   1982   "Household  Production  of  Human  Capital:   Time 
Uses  of  Parents  and  Children  as  Inputs,"  in  Financing  Education: 
Overcoming  Inefficiency  and  Inequity,  Walter  W.  McMahon  and  Terry 
Geske,  eds.,  University  of  Illinois  Press,  Urbana  and  London. 

Duncan  Greg  J   1976   "Earnings  Functions  and  Non-Pecuniary  Benefits," 
Journal  of  Human  Resources  XI,  Vol.  4,  462-83. 

Eisner  Robert  and  David  Nebhut   1981   "An  Extended  Measure  of  Govern- 
ment Product:   Preliminary  Results  for  the  U.S.  1946-76,"  in 
Income  &  Wealth,  pp.  33-64. 

Ferber  Marianne  and  Walter  McMahon  1979   "Women's  Expected  Earnings 
and  Their  Investment  in  Higher  Education,"  Journal  of  Human 
Resources ,  14  (Summer),  405-20. 

Grossman  Michael  1976   "The  Correlation  Between  Health  and  Schooling," 
in  Household  Production  and  Consumption,  N.  Terleckyj ,  ed. ,  Columbia 
University  Press  for  NBER,  New  York,  pp.  147-211. 

1982   "Determinants  of  Children's  Health,"  National 


Center  for  Health  Services  Research  Report  PHS  81-3309  and  NTIS 
P380-163603. 

Gustafson  Siv  1978   "Cost  Benefit  Analysis  of  Early  Childhood  Care 

and  Education,"  working  paper,  The  Industrial  Institute  for  Economic 
and  Social  Research,  Stockholm,  and  OECD,  May  1978. 

Hettich  Walter   1972   "Consumption  Benefits  From  Education,"  in  Canadian 
Higher  Education  in  the  Seventies ,  edited  by  Sylvia  Ostry,  Economic 
Council  of  Canada. 

Kendrick  John  W  1979   "Expanding  Imported  Values  in  the  National  In- 
come and  Product  Accounts,"  Review  of  Income  and  Wealth  (December), 
pp.  349-362. 


Oi  X>  O 

3  o.  a 

i>  i"  a.  -fc.  3  CO  3  fO  >-* 

•-=•  3 

0>  i>  rr,  en  3  -fc>  i»  h*  q 

\|\|  c  ►*  I*  l-»  "1  I"*   l-» 

co  o  w  o  '•"  o  n  o  O 

W-  rt-  ft' 

3  hO  "J  «-*  W 

(5  o  p*  o  c  o 

W  "~  <+  ~  3 

rn  ! — s  c  o  i— '.  c  3 

i/l    rt    3>  3  3  — '  tt!  3 

rr    1/1      Q.  M-  — ■  C  ►*■ 

p        g  <  £  h-  in  <  oo 

T    O    ■"*"  ">  J  H.  1^      K 

— ■  w-  3  "J  3  O  3  "5     i-* 

-.-■■  -J     I-"-  if!  O  ►"■  t'  W     -S» 

w   n    !/i  •""■  O  w  w  !■*■  ■•■£> 

j  c   <+  <+  W  •  v  <-*■  iji 

f&    — ■  ~ j  -a  CO  -'    h* 

•i  Oi     pi  IsJ  3"  I>  |\) 

~>     rf  O  O  Cl.  Q 

r->-              !-••  -h  f'.j  1~  3  "fi 

3  o   o  o  ^  •-,- 

+,  ^  h  CO  ►*■  ^  s- < 

■■0  h-  g  — ■  <u  s  w  — ■ 

i-j-  3  H-  01  3  r»  K- 

u"  -+■ ,  d  3  oi  i/i  i  3 

O     O  O  3  H-  *  O 

£   -j    O  ►*■  Ai  <+  »+  h- 

3    CO  'J1     !  "?  M-  w 

3   pj    CO         i  ■  •-' 

O  •    M  mi  3 ~ 

O       O  **   I'  o-  ■  c 

en  ■    M  3  -j 

co  ■    o  c  3  n  e  ~ 

M  •      CO  "J  3  O  0) 

O          01  C  ill  — '  3  3 

Ki  i-   pU  01 


0  v0  3    3 

CO    I-*  0*     01 

ill    f>  rr     i 

01  ■  3  i"~l 
3  I  3" 
PJ  £  I  0" 
3  !  3 
3    3  I     T3 

I     O  3    pJ 

I     O  3    w- 

I    -fc>  3    U) 

i  co  e>  3 

3  ho  • 

3    O 

3  ,\5  rr 
3    O 

CO  C) 

ill  o 

*  "" 

Oi  rt- 

3  "JO 

3  It) 


— »  O  oi 

0  O  I 

m  t-i  .— . 

r?i  iTi  ~ 

r-5  Ol 

O  O  3 

-h  M  T! 

O  & 

O  CO  i-1- 

O  0*  !U 

3  P*  3 

3  '"i 

rt>  oi  n 

—>  3  01 

n  3  3 

lt>  I  TJ 

Si  !  in 


53 


3 

T 

!"A 

H 

X' 

rg 

r& 

(_!. 

-:' 

1) 

■+ 

Oi 

rf 

■n 

n 

Q. 

[?j 

(B 

1/1 

■■ 

■■ 

Ul 

r+ 

W 

~ 

m 

<1- 

Q 

N 

01 

r+ 

0> 

Q 

^-j- 

c 

<+ 

Ul 

cri 

== 

i/i 

c 

H 

t: 

in 

rj 

3 

01 

!"~ 

— i 

m 

9i 

!"""> 

< 

3 

SB 

— * 

<-!■ 

~. 

»• 

~j 

pu 

&« 

Q. 

= 

':•:' 

'■ 

« 

m 

n 

:    : 

r-j 

JTi 

< 

Q 

_j 

f*- 

4b 

2 

< 

ij 

o 

-*j 

2> 

to 

a 

*B 

IJQ 

I? 

i~ 

-! 

-1 

SB 

i/i 

rt* 

« 

n 

X 

a. 

■  3 

it. 

j- 

SB 

:    : 

S 

1  !  | 

M 

3> 

"I 

■K 

o 

c 

m 

t  3 

■*» 

CO 


W  Oi 

rt- 

01  X  CO 

rr  rt.  o 

C  01  C 

w  a.  3 

■»  ■■  n 

rt. 

p.  n  ■■ 


een  Health  and  Education," 
I    (December),  pp.  16-22. 

'.on  or  Production?,"  Journal 
le),  pp.  569-698. 

Children,"  in  Economics  of 
l  Capital,  edited  by 
;o  Press  for  NBER,  Chicago, 


zhnologie  de  Consoramation,' 
pmmation,  CREDOC,  142 


ication,  Aptitudes  Per- 
ramiliales,"  in  Incidence 
DC,  Paris,  pp.  81-122. 

Jnited  States,  Ann  Arbor: 
•  of  Michigan. 

on  on  Efficiency  in 
•r  NBER,  New  York. 

'  Benefits  of  Education," 
iciency  and  Inequity, 
University  of  Illinois 


ment  By  Blacks  in  Higher 
1976,  2,  pp.  320-324. 

Economics  of  Higher  Educa- 
n  Britain  and  the  U.S.," 


=5 
ft 


n 

it. 


>3 


he   Monetary  Returns  to 
iteria,"  in  Financing 
lequity,  Walter  W.  McMahon 
lois  Press,  Urbana  and 


ictivity  Growth:   A 
i   and  Physical  Capital 
•  No.  752,  BEBR,  Univer- 


lon  Monetary  Returns  on 
forking  Paper,  BEBR, 


Ref 


Becker  Gary  S  1975  Hur 
Chicago  and  London. 

1976  j 


sity  of  Chicago  Pres 


1981  A 


Press,  Cambridge,  Ms 

Benham  Lee  1974  "Benef 
Economics  of  the  Fam. 
University  of  Chicag' 

Benson  Charles  S   1982 
Uses  of  Parents  and  < 
Overcoming  Ineff iciei 
Geske,  eds.,  Universi 

Duncan  Greg  J  1976  "Ea: 
Journal  of  Human  Resc 

Eisner  Robert  and  David  I 
ment  Product:  Prelin 
Income  &_  Wealth,  pp. 

Ferber  Marianne  and  Walte 
and  Their  Investment 
Resources,  14  (Summer 

Grossman  Michael  1976 

in  Household  Product:! 
University  Press  for 

1982  "D 

Center  for  Health  Ser 
P380-163603. 

Gustafson  Siv  1978  "Cos 
and  Education,"  worki 
and  Social  Research, 

Hettich  Walter  1972  "Co 
Higher  Education  in  t 
Council  of  Canada. 

Kendrick  John  W  1979  "E 
come  and  Product  Acco1 
pp.  349-362. 


/ 


. 


-11- 


Lando  Mordechai   1975   "The  Interaction  Between  Health  and  Education," 
Social  Security  Bulletin,  Vol.  38,  No.  12  (December),  pp.  16-22. 

Lazear  Edward  P   1977   "Education:   Consumption  or  Production?,"  Journal 
of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  85,  No.  3  (June),  pp.  569-698. 

Leibowitz  Arleen   1974   "Home  Investments  in  Children,"  in  Economics  of 
the  Family;   Marriage,  Children  and  Human  Capital,  edited  by 
Theodore  W.  Schultz,  University  of  Chicago  Press  for  NBER,  Chicago, 
pp.  432-452. 

Lemennicier  Bertrand   1978   "Education  et  Technologie  de  Consoramation," 
in  Incidences  de  L' Education  Sur  La  Consommation,  CREDOC,  142 
Rue  du  Chevaleret,  Paris,  pp.  1-32. 

Levy-Garbona  Louis  and  J  Jarousse   1978   "Education,  Aptitudes  Per- 
ceptives,  et  Valeur  Extraite  des  Choses  Familiales,"  in  Incidence 
de  L'Education  Sur  La  Consommation,  CREDOC,  Paris,  pp.  81-122. 

Mandell  Lewis   1972  Credit  Card  Use  in  the  United  States,  Ann  Arbor: 
Institute  for  Social  Research,  University  of  Michigan. 

Michael  Robert  T  1972  The  Effect  of  Education  on  Efficiency  in 
Consumption,  Columbia  University  Press  for  NBER,  New  York. 

1982   "Measuring  Nonmonetary  Benefits  of  Education," 


in  Financing  Education:   Overcoming  Inefficiency  and  Inequity, 
Walter  W.  McMahon  and  Terry  Geske,  eds.,  University  of  Illinois 
Press,  Urbana  and  London. 

McMahon  Walter  W  1976   "Influences  on  Investment  By  Blacks  in  Higher 
Education,"  American  Economic  Review,  May  1976,  2,  pp.  320—324. 

1974   "Policy  Issues  in  the  Economics  of  Higher  Educa- 


tion and  Related  Research  Opportunities  in  Britain  and  the  U.S.,' 
Higher  Education,  3  (1974),  pp.  165-86. 

and  Alan  P.  Wagner   1982   "The  Monetary  Returns  to 


Education  as  Partial  Social  Efficiency  Criteria,"  in  Financing 
Education:   Overcoming  Inefficiency  and  Inequity,  Walter  W.  McMahon 
and  Terry  Geske,  eds.,  University  of  Illinois  Press,  Urbana  and 
London. 

McMahon  Walter  W  1981   "The  Slowdown  in  Productivity  Growth:   A 

Macroeconomic  Model  of  Investment  in  Human  and  Physical  Capital 
with  Energy  Shocks,"  Faculty  Working  Paper  No.  752,  BEBR,  Univer- 
sity of  Illinois,  Urbana. 

1982b   "Effects  of  Expected  Non  Monetary  Returns  on 


Investment  in  Higher  Education,"  Faculty  Working  Paper,  BEBR, 
University  of  Illinois,  Urbana. 


-12- 


Psacharopoulos  George  1973  The  Returns  To  Education,  Elsevier 
Publishing  Company,  Amsterdam. 

Rumberger  Russell  W  1981  Overeducation  in  the  US  Labor  Market , 
Praeger  Publishers,  New  York. 

Schultz  Theodore  W  1967   "The  Rate  of  Return  in  Allocating  Investment 
Resources  to  Education,"  Journal  of  Human  Resources,  Vol.  7, 
No.  3,  pp.  293-309. 

1975  "The  Value  of  the  Ability  to  Deal  With  Dis- 


equilibria,"  Journal  of  Economic  Literature,  Vol.  XIII,  No.  3, 
(September),  pp.  827-846. 

Solomon  Lewis  C  1975  "The  Relation  Between  Schooling  and  Savings 
Behavior,"  in  Education,  Income ,  and  Human  Behavior,  F.  Thomas 
Juster,  ed.,  McGraw-Hill  Book  Co.  for  the  Carnegie  Commission  on 
Higher  Education,  New  York,  pp.  253-294. 

Welch  Finis  1974   "Comment,"  in  Economics  of  the  Family,  edited  by 
Theodore  W.  Schultz,  University  of  Chicago  Press  for  NBER,  pp. 
390-393. 


D/92 


HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC. 

JUN  95 

,     a  N.  MANCHESTER.] 
Bomd-To-lW  IND|ANA  46962   ^