Skip to main content

Full text of "Rural credits : land and coöperative"

See other formats


ALBERT  H.  MANN 

LIBRARY 

AT 

CORNELL  iJNIVfkSIf, 


'";';;''NELL  university  library 


3   1924  073   9 


Cornell  University 
Library 


The  original  of  tiiis  book  is  in 
the  Cornell  University  Library. 

There  are  no  known  copyright  restrictions  in 
the  United  States  on  the  use  of  the  text. 


http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924073913208 


Production  Note 
Cornell  University  Library  produced 
this  volume  to  replace  the  irreparably 
deteriorated  original .  It  was  scanned 
using  Xerox  software  and  equipment  at 
600  dots  per  inch  resolution  and 
compressed  prior  to  storage  using  ITU 
Group  4  compression.  The  digital  data 
were  used  to  create  Cornell '  s 
replacement  volume  on  paper  that  meets 
the  ANSI  Standard  Z39. 48-1992.  The 
production  of  this  volume  was 
supported  by  the  National  Endowment 
for  the  Humanities .  Digital  file 
copyright  by  Cornell  University 
Library  1995. 

Scanned  as  part  of  the  A.  R.  Mann 
Library  project  to  preserve  and 
enhance  access  to  the  Core  Historical 
Literature  of  the  Agricultural 
Sciences .  Titles  included  in  this 
collection  are  listed  in  the  volumes 
piiblished  by  the  Cornell  University 
Press  in  the  series  THE  LITERATURE  OF 
THE  AGRICULTURAL  SCIENCES,  1991-1996, 
Wallace  C.   Olsen,  series  editor. 


^tate-($nUege  of  Asttcultute 
At  (il^omell  HmoerBttg 

Htbratg 


RURAL  CREDITS 


RURAL  CREDITS 

LAND    AND    COOPERATIVE 


BY 

MYRON  T.  HERRICK 

AMERICAN  AMBAB3ADOB  TO  FBANCE 
AND 

R.  INGALLS 


NEW  YORK  AND  LONDON 
D.    APPLETON    AND     COMPANY 

1914 


Copyright,  1914,  by 
D.  APPLETON  AND  COMPANY 


Printed  in  the  United  States  of  America 


PREFACE 

The  purpose  of  this  book  is  to  throw  light  upon  the  sub- 
ject of  rural  credits  and  to  lay  before  the  American  people 
the  customs  and  lavs  in  operation  in  other  countries,  so  as 
to  prepare  the  way  for  more  enlightened  plans  for  improving 
land  and  agricultural  credit  facilities  in  the  United  States. 
It  is  my  hope  that  the  material  here  collected  will  be  helpful 
in  creating  a  credit  system  or  systems  adapted  to  the  needs 
of  the  agricultural  interests  of  this  country. 

The  subject  ef  rural  credits  has  occupied  my  attention, 
more  or  less,  for  a  considerable  number  of  years,  and  I  have 
availed  myself  of  the  opportunities  of  my  position  as  Amer- 
ican Ambassador  to  France  to  familiarize  myself  with  agri- 
cultural conditions  and  credit  systems  and  institutions  in 
Europe.  Furthermore,  my  twenty-eight  years'  connection, 
with  the  Society  for  Savings  in  the  City  of  Cleveland,  as 
treasurer,  chairman  of  the  board,  and  president,  has  been  of 
great  value  to  me  in  the  formation  of  ideas  regarding  financial 
questions,  and  especially  with  respect  to  cooperative  credit. 
The  Society  for  Savings,  with  nearly  one  hundred  thousand 
depositors,  is  one  of  the  largest  of  the  mutual  savings  banks 
in  the  country.  It  has  no  capital  stock;  it  is  mutual  in  its 
organization  and  administration,  and  was  founded  primarily 
for  the  purpose  of  encouraging  thrift.  Indeed,  for  several 
years,  I  have  deemed  it  a  patriotic  duty  to  investigate  the 
rural-credit  systems  and  institutions  of  various  nations  and 
to  give  my  fellow-citizens  the  results  of  my  research. 

The  project  for  improving  farm-credit  facilities  and  intro- 
ducing cooperation  credit  in  the  United  States  is  not  a  new  one. 
In  an  article  published  in  the  Journal  of  Social  Science  in 
1869,  Henry  ViUard,  the  railroad  builder,  gave  an  interesting 
account  of  the  Schulze-DeHtzsch  banks,  and  remarked  that 


vi  PEEFACB 

"they  can  safely  be  recommended  for  adoption  in  this  coun- 
try." In  1893  the  Department  of  Agriculture  published  a 
bulletin  prepared  by  Edward  T.  Peters  on  "Cooperative 
Credit  Associations  in  Certain  European  Countries."  This 
document,  which  is  still  the  best  published  by  the  Government 
on  these  topics,  described  the  systems  of  cooperative  credit  in 
Germany,  Austria-Hungary,  Italy,  and  Eussia.  In  1901  An- 
drew McFarland  Davis  prepared  for  the  American  Economic 
Association,  and  published  in  the  association's  Quarterly,  the 
history  of  "Currency  and  Banking  m  the  Province  of  Massa- 
chusetts-Bay." This  work,  which  should  be  carefully  read 
by  legislators  proposing  laws  for  improving  land  credit, 
explains  the  causes  of  the  failures  of  the  land  banks  which 
were  established  iu  some  of  the  American  colonies  iu  the  first 
half  of  the  eighteenth  century.  The  reports  of  the  National 
Monetary  Commission,  appointed  ia  1907,  eontaiu  valuable 
information  on  land-banks  and  cooperative  credit  systems  of 
Europe.  All  this  shows  that  the  problems  of  rural  credits 
had  engaged  the  official  attention  of  the  Government  before 
the  launching  of  the  recent  movement.  In  fact,  since  the  col- 
lapse of  the  farm  mortgage  "craze"  in  the  early  nineties,  the 
farmers'  interests  have  been  a  subject  of  consideration  by  all 
those  who  have  been  studying  the  question  of  currency  re- 
form. 

On  November  22,  1908,  a  cooperative  savings  and  loan 
society  was  established  at  Manchester,  New  Hampshire,  for 
French-Canadian  lumbermen  working  during  the  winter  in 
the  New  Hampshire  woods.  Some  of  the  members  were  resi- 
dents of  the  agricultxiral  districts  of  Quebec  in  which  Al- 
phonse  Desjardins'  bank  was  in  operation.  In  1909,  through 
the  influence  of  Pierre  Jay,  bank  commissioner,  the  Massa- 
chusetts Legislature  enacted  a  credit-union  law,  a  fact  which 
did  not  become  widely  known  until  several  years  later.  In 
1910  a  thesis  on  "Cooperative  Credit  Associations  of  the 
Province  of  Quebec,"  submitted  by  Hector  Macpherson  to 
the  faculty  of  the  Graduate  School  of  Arts  and  Literature  of 
the  University  of  Chicago,  first  attracted  the  attention  of  the 
American  public  to  the  work  of  Mr.  Desjardins  in  Quebec. 


PREFACE  vii 

The  question  was  begiiming  to  be  widely  discussed  in 
1910,  and  during  the  summer  of  that  year,  while  on  a  trip 
to  Europe,  I  obtained,  through  Eobert  Skinner,  then  consul- 
general  at  Hamburg,  statistics  and  particulars  regarding  the 
cooperative  land-credit  systems  of  Germany.  This  informa- 
tion I  used  in  a  speech  delivered  at  Delaware,  Ohio,  on  Octo- 
ber 26,  1910,  before  Group  Five  of  the  Ohio  Bankers'  Asso- 
ciation. After  that  I  began  a  thorough  investigation  of  the 
subject,  and  became  so  deeply  interested  that  I  brought  the 
matter  by  resolution  before  the  American  Bankers'  Associa- 
tion at  its  annual  meeting  of  1911  in  New  Orleans.  On  No- 
vember 24,  1911,  the  Association  instructed  its  Committee  on 
Agricultural  and  Financial  Education  and  Development 
(then  formed)  to  investigate  the  general  subject  of  rural 
finance  in  relation  to  conditions  in  the  United  States.  Sev- 
eral months  earlier,  in  the  same  year,  the  Jewish  Agricul- 
tural and  Industrial  Aid  Society  had  begun  actually  to  form 
cooperative  credit  societies  for  farmers. 

President  Taft  was  so  much  impressed  with  the  impor- 
tance of  the  problem  of  rural  credits  that  he  directed  Secre- 
tary of  State  Kjiox  to  instruct  the  embassies  in  Germany  and 
Italy  and  the  legations  ia  Belgium  and  the  Netherlands  to 
make  investigations  in  the  matter  of  land  credit.  In  a  letter 
addressed  to  me  on  March  30,  1912,  the  Secretary  said: 

These  missions  are  being  instructed  simultaneously  to  send 
copies  of  their  reports  to  the  Embassy  at  Paris,  which  is  re- 
quested to  undertake  the  duty  of  preparing  a  general  report, 
with  all  proper  exhibits  and  documents  such  as  will  place  the 
Department  in  possession  of  all  data  necessary,  to  the  Presi- 
dent for  the  formulation  of  some  practical  scheme  which  may 
be  worked  out  to  bring  the  desired  benefits  to  the  agricultural 
communities  in  the  United  States.  If  there  are  any  other 
countries  where  such  arrangements  are  already  in  operation, 
the  Department  will,  from  time  to  time,  be  glad  to  supplement 
the  present  instructions  with  further  instructions. 

On  April  1,  1912,  at  its  meeting  at  Nashville,  Tenn.,  the 
Southern  Commercial  Congress,  at  the  suggestion  of  David 


viii  PEEFACE 

Lubin,  American  delegate  to  the  International  Institute  of 
Agriculture,  held  a  conference  on  rural  cooperative  credit. 
On  April  17,  1912,  Senator  Porter  J.  McCumber,  of  North 
Dakota,  presented  in  the  Senate  and  had  published  as  a  public 
document  an  outline  of  European  rural  cooperative  credit, 
compiled  by  the  Institute  on  February  26, 1912.  On  June  22 
of  that  year,  the  EepubUcan  Party  at  its  convention  at  Chi- 
cago adopted  as  one  of  its  planks  a  resolution  indorsing  the 
movement,  prepared  according  to  my  suggestions.  Similar 
resolutions  were  adopted  subsequently  by  the  Democratic  and 
Progressive  parties  at  their  conventions. 

On  October  11,  1912,  the  Government  at  Washington, 
through  the  Department  of  State,  published  the  "Prelim- 
inary Eeport  on  Land  and  Agricultural  Credit,"  which  I  had 
compiled  at  Paris  with  the  assistance  of  Edwin  Chamberlain, 
of  San  Antonio,  Texas;  Edward  N.  Breitung,  of  Marquette, 
Michigan,  and  E.  Ingalls,  of  Atchison,  Kansas.  In  formu- 
lating the  recommendations  in  that  report,  I  found  extremely 
useful  the  suggestions  and  information  furnished  by  M.  De- 
charme,  of  the  French  Ministry  of  Agriculture;  Hippolyte 
Morel,  president  of  the  Credit  Foncier  of  France;  Georges 
PaUaiQ,  governor  of  the  Bank  of  France;  Henry  W.  Wolff, 
the  BngHsh  authority  on  cooperative  credit;  Curtis  Guild, 
then  Ambassador  to  Eussia;  John  G.  A.  Leishman,  formerly 
Ambassador  to  Germany;  Eichard  C.  Kerens,  formerly  Am- 
bassador to  Austria,  and  Maurice  Francis  Egan,  formerly 
Minister  to  Denmark.  The  report  was  sent  to  the  governors 
of  the  states,  accompanied  by  a  personal  letter  of  President 
,Taft  approving  its  recommendations  and  inviting  the  govern- 
ors to  a  special  conference,  which  was  held  at  the  White  House 
on  December  7,  1912. 

President  Wilson  proclaimed  his  advocacy  of  the  rural- 
credits  movement  in  his  inaugural  address,  and  on  March  4, 
1913,  an  act  was  passed  by  Congress  for  the  appointment  by 
the  President  of  a  United  States  Commission  to  go  to  Europe 
with  the  American  Commission  assembled  by  the  Southern 
Commercial  Congress  for  the  purpose  of  making  an  investiga- 
tion and  report  on  agricultural  finance,  production,  distribu- 


PEEFACE  ix 

tion,  and  rural  life  in  Europe.  The  commissions  sailed  on 
April  36,  1913.  The  evidence  of  the  American  Commission 
was  submitted  to  the  Senate  on  October  30,  1913,  and  its  ob- 
servations and  a  minority  report  on  December  5,  1913.  The 
reports  of  the  United  States  Commission  were  submitted  to 
ihe  Senate  on  January  29  and  March  13,  1914. 

As  a  result  of  the  movement,  several  states  have  enacted 
laws  to  improve  rural  credit  facilities,  and  there  are  numer- 
ous biUs  of  the  same  purport  pending  in  Congress  and  the 
state  legislatures.  It  cannot  be  said  that  the  legislation 
enacted  or  proposed  is  entirely  satisfactory.  Indeed,  neither 
bankers  nor  farmers,  as  a  class,  have  given  it  their  unqualified 
approval.  The  trouble  seems  to  lie  in  an  attempt  to  apply 
European  principles  to  American  conditions  without  ade- 
quately studying  the  credit  institutions  and  systems  devised 
for  farmers  and  landowners  in  European  and  the  few  other 
countries  where  they  have  been  developed. 

In  preparing  this  book,  I  have  tried  to  supply  facts  and 
figures  regardtag  these  institutions  and  systems.  For  this 
reason  it  is  largely  descriptive.  The  information  which  it 
contains  has  been  drawn  from  public  documents  and  original 
sources,  and  every  effort  has  been  made  to  have  it  compre- 
hensive and  accurate. 

Mteon  T.  Heeeick. 
Embassy  op  the  United  States  op  Ameeica, 
Pakis,  Pbance. 

September  1,  1914. 


CONTENTS 

PAET   I.    LAND   CEEDITl 

CHAPTBB  PAGE 

I.    CEEDIT,  ITS  FOEMS  AND  USE  .        .        .     ,'.        .        3 

Definition. — Forms  of  Credit. — ^Agricultural  Credit  in 
the  United  States. — ^Farmers'  Debt,  Its  Possible  Ex- 
pansion.— ^Long-term  Loans  and  Short-term  Loans. — 
Federal  Eeserve  Act  of  1913. — Cooperative  Banking 
■  System  for  Farmers. — ^European  Models. 

n.    SPECIAL  PRIVILEGE  AND  STATE  AID  ...      11 

Substitution  of  Companies  for  Individual  Money 
Lenders. — ^Break-up  of  Feudal  System  in  Europe. — 
Special  Privileges  for  Determining  Titles. — ^Necessities 
of  European  Peasants. — Two  European  Classes  of  Or- 
ganizations for  Lending  Money. — American  Need  of 
Long-term,  Eeducible  Loans. 

m.    LONG-TEEM  LOANS  AND  AMOETIZATION    ,        .  "^  17 

Definition. — Four  Methods  of  Extiuguishing  a  Loan. 
— ^History  of  Amortization  Plan. — Two  Advantages  of 
Amortizable  Loans  Repayable  by  Annuities. — Relation 
of  Value  of  Land  to  Loans. — ^Amortization  Impossible 
for  Ordinary  Money  Lenders. — Absolute  Safety  Neces- 
sary for  Bonds  of  Amortization  Companies. — ^Deben- 
tures the  Key  to  the  System. 

IV.    DEBENTURES 24 

Land  as  the  Basis  for  Issue  of  Paper  Money. — ^History 
of  Experiments  in  England,  Prussia,  France,  and  the 
Colonies. — ^Land  Good  as  Such  Basis  Only  if  Owned 
by   Government.— Not    Possible    as   Basis  for   Bank  ' 
Loans. — Characteristics  of  Debentures. 

xi 


xii  CONTENTS 

CHAPTBB  FAGI!  ) 

V.    THE  ORIGIN  OF  THE  GERMAN  LANDSCHAFTS   .      34  "^ 

German  InstitutioBs  for  Credit. — ^Number  and  Loca- 
tion of  Landsehafts. — Definition  of  Landschaft. — 
Landsahafts  Now  Voluntary  But  First  Compulsory. — 
Origin  in  Prussia  After  Seven  Years'  War. — Biiring'3 
Plan. — ^Arguments  for  the  Scheme. — ^Adoption  and 
Success. 

VI.    THE  SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT :  ITS  STEUCTITRE  .      45 

Organization. — Executive  Council. — ^District  Boards. — 
Standing  Committees. — General  Assembly. — ^Permanent 
Committee. — Circles. — Bank  of  the  Silesian  Land- 
schaft.— Bureaus  of  Loans  to  Non-members. 

Vn.    THE  SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  OPERATION  .      58 

Methods  of  Bank  and  of  Bureaus  for  Non-members. — 
Obligations  of  Landschaft. — Procedure  in  Obtaining  a 
Loan. — ^Forms  of  Debentures  Received:  Litera  A  and 
Litera  C. — Obligations  of  Borrowers. — ^Benefits  to 
Members. — ^Rights  of  Borrowers. — Liabilities  in  Case 
of  Default. — Loans  to  Non-members. — ^Landschaft 
Bank. 

Vin.    THE  SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  FUNDS  AND 

DEBENTURES 68 

Investment  of  Interest. — General  Fund. — ^Amortization 
Fund. — Guaranty  Fund. — Bank  Fund. — ^Accounts. — 
R«ports'. — ^Denominations  of  Debentures.*-Debenture3 
Only  in  Exchange  for  Mortgage  Contracts. — Rights  of 
Debenture  Holders. — Redemption  of  Debentures  on  Re- 
payment of  Loan. — Debentures  as  Investments. — 
Litera  B  Debentures. — Condition  of  Silesian  Land- 
schaft in  1912. 

Et,    THE  OTHER  GERMAN  LANDSCHAFTS    ...      77 

Old  Type  of  Landsehafts  in  Prussia. — Stat©  Aid. — 
Variations  in  Different  Provinces. — ^Management, 
Members  and  OfScers. — Credit  and  Debentures. — 
Changes  After  Napoleonic  Wars. — Privilege  of  RecaU- 
iug  the  Loan. — Reduction  of  Interest. — The  "Con- 
version."— Creation  of  a  Sinking  Fund. — ^Posen's 
Provincial  Credit  Association. — The  New  Debentures. 
— ^Amortization  of  Loans  by  Annuities. — ^Extension  of 
Landschaft  to  Common  People. — ^Reduction  of  Mini- 
mum for  Credit. — Variations  Among  New  Landsehafts. 
— Central  Landschaft. 


CONTENTS  xiii 

CHAPTBS  PAGE 

X.    GERMAN  PUBLIC  LAND-CEEDIT  INSTITUTIONS      92 

Land-credit  Institutions  Other  Than  Landschafts. — 
Necessity  for  Their  Creation. — Three  Classes. — Land- 
credit  Banks. — Original  Purpose  to  Commute  Peudal 
Servitudes. — Present  Purpose  to  Supply  Cheap  Money 
on  Land  Security. — Operation. — ^Land  Improvement 
Annuity  Banks. — ^Purpose  to  Finance  Land-improve- 
ment Projects. — Operation. — Settlement  Commission. — 
Purpose  to  Create  Small  Homesteads. — ^History. — 
Operation. — State  Invalidity  and  Old-age  Insurance 
Institutions. 


XT.    PRIVATE  SOURCES  OP  LAND  CREDIT  IN  GER- 
MANY        101 

Long-term  Reducible  Loans  Made  by  Public  Credit 
Institutions. — Short-term  Loans  Represented  by  Sec- 
ond Mortgages. — Savings  Banks. — ^Their  Operation. — 
Mortgage  Loans. — Private  Insurance  Institutions. — 
Real-estate  Loans  Not  on  Farm  Lands. — Coopera- 
tive Credit  Societies. — Land-credit  Banks. — History. — 
Bonds.  —  OflScial  Supervision.  —  Operation. — Bavarian 
Mortgage  and  Exchange  Bank  of  Munich. — ^Prussian 
Central  Land-credit  Company. — History  and  Operation. 

XU.    FRANCE:  THE  CREDIT  FONCLER    .        .        .        .111 

Legislatisu. — ^History  of  Land-credit  Movement. — 
Creation  of  the  Credit  Foncier. — ^Privileges. — Organi- 
zation.— Capital  Stock. — Purpose. — Two  Sources  of 
Funds. — ^Long-term  Loans. — Syndical  Associations. — 
Long-term  Leases. — ^Amount  of  Loan. — ^Application  for 
Loan . — The  Purge. — Terms  and  Penalties. — Use  of  De- 
bentures.— Premiums. — Special  Privileges. 

TTTT.    FRANCE:  LAND  CREDIT  FOE  AGRICULTURE        .    128 

Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  de  Batiment. — Sub- 
sidiary Company  to  Credit  Foncier. — Operations  and 
Management. — Applications  for  Credit. — ^Long-term 
Credit. — Statistics  of  Operations. — ^Not  the  Intended 
Aid  to  Agriculture. — ^Reason  in  Its  Centralization. 
— Central  Bank  for  Agricultural  Loans. — ^Long- 
term  Loans  to  Associations  through  Credit  Agrieole 
MutueL — Long-term  Loans  to  Individuals.  —  Two 
Methods  of  Amortization. 


xiv  CONTENTS 

CHAPTEB  FAGS 

XIV.    ITALY 136 

Present  Institutions. — History  of  Land  Credit. — 
Failures  Due  to  Overlooking  Farmers'  Interests. — 
Istituto  Italiano  di  Credito  Fondiario  of  1891. — 
Banks  of  Issue. — Present  Savings  Banks. — Land- 
credit  Business  Kept  Separate. — Loan  Seeurily. — 
Interest. — Debentures. — ^Payments. — Capital  Stock  of 
Istituto  Italiano. — Powers  of  Company. — ^Emphy- 
teusis.— ^Agricultural  Credit  Given  by  Savings,  Com- 
mercial and  Cooperative  Banks,  the  Monti  Frumen- 
tarii,  and  Associations  of  Land  Owners. 

XV.    SMALL   HOLDINGS   IN"   GREAT    BRITAIN  AND 

IRELAND 148 

Act  of  1908  Enables  Government  to  Take  Private 
Land. — Land  Leased  in  Small  Holdings. — County 
Councils  in  Charge  of  Leasing. — ^Procedure. — Forma- 
tion of  Cooperative  Associations. — Land  Court  of 
Scotland. — ^Land  Holders  and  Small  Holders. — Work 
of  Scotch  Board  of  Agriculture. — ^Four  Official  Bodies 
in  Ireland. — Large  Loans  of  Board  of  Works. — 
Congested  Districts  Board  in  West  of  Ireland. — ^Iriah 
Department  of  Agriculture  and  Technical  Instruction. 
— Credit  of  State  Extended  by  Estate  Commissioners 
for  Acquiring  Real  Estate. — ^Progress  of  Work. — 
History  of  Land-purchase  Legislation. — ^Aets  Admin- 
istered by  Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries. 

XVT.    AUSTRIA-HUNGARY,   RUSSIA,  AND   THE   BAL- 
KAN STATES 161 

Provincial  Mortgage  Institutions  of  Austria. — Their 
Loans. — History  of  These  Institutions. — Land  Credit 
in  Hungary. — ^Hungarian  Boden-Kredit  Institut. — 
Administration. — ^National  Land  Credit  Institute  for 
Small  Holders. — ^National  Federation  of  Hungarian 
Land  Credit  Institutions. — ^Land  Credit  Institute  at 
Nagy-Szeben. — Large  Russian  Projects. — Colonization 
of  Siberia. — ^Peasants'  State  Land  Bank. — ^Distribu- 
tion of  Land  to  Emancipated  Serfs. — Operations  of 
the  Bank. — Work  of  the  Land  Commissioners. — ^Aid 
for  Home  Colonization  in  Finland. — ^Rural  Banks  of 
Communes. — ^Mortgage  Society  of  Finland. — Terri- 
torial Credit  in  Livonia,  Esthonia,  and  Courland. — 
Government  Confiscation  of  Nobility's  Estates  in 
Roumania. — ^Landschaft  System  and  Rural  Bank. — 
Bond  and  Mortgage  Institution  of  Servia. 


CONTENTS 


XV 


CHAPTBB 

XVIL 


SWITZEELAND,  DENMARK,  AND  SCANDINAVIA 

Numerous  Swiss  Land-credit  Institutions. — Unique 
Mortgage  Banks. — ^Danish  Associations  Like  Gemuux 
Landschafts. — Mortgage  Associations  in  Denmark. — 
Mortgage  Bank  of  the  Kingdom  of  Denmark. — Home 
Colonization  Policy. — Landowners'  Mortgage  Asso- 
ciations.— Swedish  General  Mortgage  Bank. — Appro- 
priations by  Swedish  Government. — State  Aid  in  Nor- 
way.— ^Work  Done  through  Norwegian  Bank  for 
Laborers'  Holdings  and  DweUings. 


PAGB 

176 


XVIU.    LAND  CEEDIT  OUTSIDE  OF  EUROPE 


.    187 


Land-credit  Institutions  in  Egypt. — ^Land-credit  Sys- 
tem of  Japan. — ^Agricultural  Bank  of  the  Philippines. 
— State  Banks  of  Australia. — Queensland  Agricul- 
tural Bank. — State  Aid  for  Home  Colonization  in 
New  Zealand. — Mexican  Land  Mortgage  Banks  and 
Promotion  Banks. — Three  Land-credit  Institutions  in 
Argentine  Eepublic. — ^Early  and  Successful  Land 
Credit  in  ChUe. — ^Banco  Hipotecario  del  Uruguay. — 
Costa  Eiea's  State  Land-mortgage  Bank. — Territorial 
Bank  of  Cuba. — ^Development  in  Europe  and  America 
of  Loans  on  Life  Insurance  Policies. 


XIX.    THE    PRINCIPLES     OF    LAND    CEEDIT     AND 

THEIE  APPLICATION 209 

Distinguishable  Feature  of  Land-credit  Institutions 
the  Power  to  Issue  Debentures. — These  Not  Possible 
to  Usual  Money  Lenders. — Private  Institutions  and 
Landschafts. — Loans  Made  to  Special  Classes. — 
Eegulations  and  Powers. — Organizations  of  European 
Countries  Compared. — Security  of  Loans. — ^UnreeaU- 
able  Long-term  Debenture  Necessary  for  Long-term 
Credit. — Situation  in  United  States  and  Europe. — 
Comparison  of  Silesian  Landschaft  and  Possible  Or- 
ganization in  Kansas. — ^Wisconsin  Land  Mortgage 
Associations  Act. — ^Land  Bank  of  the  State  of  New 
York. — ^Eural  Business  of  Savings  and  Loan  Associa- 
tions.— Ohio. — CoUeetive  Saving  Different  from  Co- 
operative Credit. — ^Desirability  of  American  Land- 
schafts. 


xvi  CONTENTS 


PART   II.    COOPERATIVE   CREDIT 

CHAFTBB  PA6B 

XX.    COOPEEATION  AND  COOPEEATIVE  CREDIT      .    247 

Definition.  —  Administration. — Objects. — Cooperative 
Society  versus  Partnership  and  Corporation. — ^His- 
tory of  Corporations. — Eise  of  Modem  Cooperation. 
— English  Trade  Unions. — ^Beginnings  in  Germany 
and  Prance. — Work  of  Schnlze-Delitzsch  for  Trades- 
people and  Workingmen. — ^Eaiffeisen's  Activities  for 
Agriculturists. — Luigi  Luzzatti. — ^Advantage  of  Co- 
operation for  Farmers. — Two  Arrangements  in 
Europe. 

XXT.     THE  SCHTILZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS  .  .-263 

Early  Life  of  Sohulze. — ^Founding  of  Associations  for 
Workingmen. — ^Political  Career. — Later  Loan  Asso- 
ciations.— Spread  of  Movement. — ^Attitude  of  Prus- 
sian Government. — ^Death  and  Beputation  of  Schulze. 
— Henry  Charles  Carey. — Claude-Frederic  Bastiat. — 
Scotch  Banks  and  "Character"  Credit. — ^Plan  of 
Schulze  People's  Bank. — Operation  and  Organization 
of  a  Bank. — Objection  to  Centralization. 

XXn.    THE  EAIFFEISEN  SYSTEM 281 

Life  and  Character  of  Eaiffeisen. — ^Early  Work  for 
Cooperation. — Change  from  Charity  to  Self-help. 
— Growth  of  Societies. — ^Differences  from  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  System. — Central  Agricultural  Land  Bank. 
— General  Federation  of  the  Eural  Cooperative  So- 
cieties.— ^Eeasons  for  Success  of  His  Principles. — 
Agricultural  Cooperation  and  Combination  His  Con- 
tribution. ^' 

XXrn.     GEEMAN  SYSTEMS  AT  PRESENT  .        .        .        .296 

Distributive  Societies  of  William  Haas. — ^Imperial 
Federation  of  Agricultural  Cooperative  Societies 
and  the  Raiffeisen  General  Federation. — ^Unions, 
or  Local  Cooperative  Associations. — State  Aid. — 
Income  and  Audit  of  the  Unions. — Examples  of 
Failures  Among  Societies  and  Banks. — Cooperative 
Banks  for  Agricultural  Systems. — Prussian  Central 
Cooperative  Bank. — Small  Credit  Societies  at  Base 
of  Whole  System. — Their  Organization,  Rules,  and 
Liabilities.--Statistics. 


CONTENTS 


xvu 


CEAPTIS 

XXIV, 


PAGE 

321 


AGEICTILTTJEAL  CREDIT  IN  PEANCE 

Early  Cooperative  Movement  in  France. — Credit 
Agricole  Mutuel. — History  of  Society. — Soei^te  du 
Credit  Agricole. — ^Its  Failure  Due  to  Method  of 
Organization. — Further  Attempts. — La'ws  of  1867 
and  1884. — Associations  and  Comices. — Syndicats 
Professionels. — Syndical  Banks  and  Connection 
■with  Bank  of  France. — Organization  and  Opera- 
tion of  Banks  of  the  System. — Government  Loans. 

XXV.     ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOBG    .        .    346 

Lnzzatti  and  His  Cooperative  Credit  Bank. — ^De- 
partures from  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Baiffeisen 
Systems. — ^Legislation. — Management. — ^Business. — 
WoUemborg  and  Kural  Credit  Societies. — ^National 
Federation  of  Eural  Credit  Societies. — Position  of 
the  Church. — Success  of  the  Associations. — Special 
Laws  for  the  South. — Government  Aid. — Casse 
Ademprivili  of  Sardinia. — Central  Banks  versus 
Local  Organizations. 

XXVI.    THE  DtTAL  MONAECHT 364 

Conditions  in  Austria. — Early  Cooperative  Move- 
ments.— Schulze-Delitzsch  Banks  and  Baiffeisen 
Credit  Societies  in  Austria. — German  Federation 
of  Austrian  Agricultural  Cooperative  Societies. — 
State  and  Provincial  Aid. — Conditions  in  Hungary. 
— ^Early  Cooperative  Movement  and  Count  Karolyi 
— ^Hungarian  Central  Society  for  Cooperative 
Credit,  the  Centre. — Organization,  Duties  and  Priv- 
ileges.— Success  and  Failures  of  Hungarian  Credit 
System. — ^Three  Types  of  Cooperative  Organiza- 
tion Independent  of  the  Centre. 

XXVn.    BELGIUM,     HOLLAND,     LtrXEMBtlBG,     DEN- 
MARK, SCANDINAVIA,  AND  SWITZEELAND    .    380 

Cooperative  Credit  Early  Devised  in  Belgium. — 
Credit  Union  of  Brussels. — ^Farmers  Not  Benefited. 
Comptoir  Agricole  and  the  Genieral  Pension  and 
Savings  Bank. — The  Boerenbond. — Syndicates. — 
Village  Associations  in  HoUand. — The  Catholic 
Church. — Eindhoven  Central  Bank. — Central  Banks 
at  Utrecht  and  Aikmaar. — High  Degree  of  Co- 
operation in  Luxemburg. — State  Banks. — Coopera- 
tion for  Buying  and  Selling  in  Denmark.— jGov- 
emment  Encouragement  of  Eural  Credit  Societies. 


XVUl 


CONTENTS 


— Mortgage-bond  Companies  of  Norway. — Early 
Cooperative  Associations  for  Sweden. — Baiffeisen 
Societies  in  Switzerland. — Swiss  Union  of  Eaif- 
feisen  Banks. — Small  Banks  and  Ample  Credit. — 
Cattle-purchasing  Commissions  of  Thurgan. 

XXVm.    EUSSIA  AND  THE  BALKA.N  STATES  . 

Activity  of  Cooperative  Societies  in  Russia. — The 
Artel. — ^Early  Cooperative  Loan  and  Savings  So- 
ciety.— ^Moscow  Agricultural  Association. — Schulze- 
Delitzsch  Banks. — Credit  Societies. — General  Board 
for  Small  Credit  and  the  Bank  of  Russia. — Legis- 
lation and  Government  Aid. — ^Zemstvo  Banks. — 
Moscow  People's  Banks. — Conditions  in  Finland. — 
Highly  Centralized  Cooperation. — Central  Coopera- 
tive Credit  Establishment. — People's  Banks  in  Eou- 
mania. — Central  Bank. — State  Aid. — Servian  Banks 
of  EaifEeisen  Type. — Joint-stock  Central  Bank. 
— General  Union. — ^Public  Granaries. — Farmers ' 
Banks  of  Bulgaria. — Central  Agricultural  Bank. — 
Unique  Central  Cooperative  Bank. — Cooperative 
Attempts  in  Turkey  and  Cyprus. — Cooperation 
Among  Jewish  Colonists  in  Palestine. 


XXIX.    SPAIN  AND  PORTUGAL 


395 


415 


Positos. — Need  of  Credit. — Operations  of  Positos. 
— ^Recent  Credit  Societies. — The  Leo  XIII,  the 
Bank  of  Spain  and  the  Mortgage  Bank. — Govern- 
ment Help  for  Cooperative  Societies. — ^Misericor- 
dias  and  CeUeiros  Communs  of  Portugal. — ^Modern 
Agricultural  Mutual  Credit  System. — Agricultural 
Credit  Board  and  Bank  of  Portugal. — Republics 
of  Andorra  and  San  Marino. — Monaco  and  Lioh- 
tenstein. 

XXX.    BRITISH   INDIA,   JAPAN,   EGYPT,   AND   THE 

AFRICAN  COLONIES 427 

Conditions  in  India. — The  Kuttuchuttu  and  Nidhis. 
— ^Work  of  Nicholson  and  Wolff. — Cooperative 
Credit  Ldws  of  1904  and  1912. — Development  of 
Societies. — Statistics. — Early  Mutual  Aid  Societies 
in  Japan. — Law  of  1909. — Central  Association  of 
Cooperative  Societies. — Attempts  in  Egypt. — So- 
ciety of  Omar  Lufty  Bey. — Credit  System  in  Al- 
geria and  Tunis. — Provident  Societies. — Thrift  So- 
cieties of  French  West  Africa. — Credit  Societies  in 
Java,  Windhoek. 


CONTENTS 


THY 


CHAFTBB  PAGE 

XXSJ.    GEEAT    BRITAIN,   IRELAND,    CANADA,    AND 

THE  UNITED  STATES 439 

Iriah  Agricultural  Organization.  —  Sir  Horace 
Plunkett. — ^Doneraile  Credit  Society. — Progress  of 
Eural  Cooperative  Credit  Not  Satisfactory. — Agri- 
cultural Organization  Society  for  England  and 
Wales. — Organization  and  Management. — Scottish 
Agricultural  Organization  Society. — Caisse  Popu- 
laire  of  Quebec. — ^Legislation  of  1906. — Cooperative 
Credit  in  Preneh  Canada. — Cooperative  Credit 
Among  Jewish  Farmers  of  the  United  States. — 
General  Agitation .  of  Bural  Credit  Idea. — Jewish 
Bural  Cooperative  Banks. — Other  Cooperative  At- 
tempts by  Jews  in  North  and  South  America. 

yyyrr.   the  principles  of  coopeeative  ceedit 

AND  THEIE  APPLICATION 456 

Spread  of  Cooperative  Credit  in  Europe  and  Asia. 
— Building  and  Loan  Associations  and  Savings 
Banks  in  the  United  States. — Mutual  and  Co- 
operative Insurance. — No  Eural  Cooperative  Credit 
System  in  This  Country. — Characteristics  of 
European  System. — Two  Classes  of  Eural  Credit 
Societies:  Limited  Liability  with  Shares  and  Un- 
limited Liability  Paying  No  Dividends. — Simple 
and  Uniform  Legislation  Desirable. — ^Function  of 
Cooperative  Systems  to  Eeceive  Deposits  and  Ac- 
cord Credit  on  Security  Other  Than  Eeal  Estate. 
— ^Popular  Misconceptions  as  to  European  Societies. 
— Advantages  of  a  Cooperative  Credit  Society. — 
Credit  for  Members  and  Collective  Purchase  and 
Sale. — Threefold  Structure  of  European  System. — 
Procedure  in  Formation  of  a  Eural  Cooperative 
Credit  Society. — The  Development. — Necessity  for 
New  Laws  in  United  States. 


INDEX 


431 


PAET  L  LAND  CREDIT 


CHAPTER  I 

CEEDIT,    ITS    FOEMS    AKD    USE 

Definition. — ^Fonns  of  Credit. — Agricultural  Credit  in  the  United 
States. — Farmers'  Debt,  Its  Possible  Expansion. — Long-term 
Loans  and  Short-term  Loans. — Federal  Eeserve  Act  of  1913. — 
Cooperative   Banking  System  for  Farmers. — ^European  Models. 

In  a  financial  sense,  credit  is  that  confidence  reposed  in 
a  person,  which  enables  him  to  obtain  from  another  the  tem- 
porary use  of  a  thing  of  value.  It  may  be  accorded  on  the 
security  of  real  estate,  personal  property,  or  mere  character; 
and  so  is  classified  in  three  general  forms  deriving  their 
names  from  the  kind  of  security  taken. 

Credit  in  any  one  of  these  three  forms  may  be  either  con- 
sumptive or  productive  according  to  the  purpose  of  its  use. 
The  purchase  on  time  of  a  luxury  or  an  unnecessary  thing,  or 
the  renewal  of  an  old  debt  on  more  onerous  terms,  is  called  con- 
sumptive because  such  acts  decrease  the  wealth  of  the  debtor. 
This  form  is  dangerous.  "Credit  supports  the  borrower  as 
the  rope  supports  the  hanged,"  said  Louis  XIV  in  the  seven- 
teenth century  when  he  saw  how  the  nobles  through  extrava- 
gance and  the  peasantry  through  thrrftlessness  had  fallen 
into  the  clutches  of  usurers. 

Productive  credit  is  that  which  is  employed  to  stop  a  lossi 
effect  an  economy,  or  create  something  materially  valuable. 
The  savings  or  gains  which  result  ought  eventually  to  equal 
the  debt :  hence  no  one  need  be  afraid  of  this  form,  provided 
the  amount  and  extent  be  judiciously  limited  to  ability  for 
prompt  repayment.  As  is  popularly  said,  productive  credit 
makes  its  own  security  and  liquidates  itself. 

Again,  credit  is  either  short-term  or  long-term.  Short- 
term  credit  is  properly  a  banking  operation.     Chattel  mort- 

3 


4  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

gages,  easily  negotiable  collateral,  and  the  endorsement  of 
responsible  parties  are  the  securities  taken  for  it.  Eeal-estate 
mortgages  are  usually  reserved  for  long-term  credit.  Only 
relatively  small  numbers  of  these  reach  the  banks.  As  a  rule, 
they  are  used  for  the  investment  of  funds  whose  owners  do 
not  require  a  quick  return  of  the  principal.  Finally,  credit  is 
called  individual  when  accorded  to  persons  separately,  and  col- 
lective or  cooperative  wheii  accorded  to  groups  of  persons. 

The  bulk  of  the  world's  business  is  done  on  credit.  Na- 
tions, municipalities  and  public  corporations  are  bonded  be- 
yond thought  of  redemption  by  the  present  generation.  In- 
dustrial companies  and  commercial  houses  operate  in  a  large 
measure  on  borrowed  capital  and  banks  on  deposits  entrusted 
to  their  care.  Business  concerns  of  all  kinds  are  continually 
receiving  and  giving  credit.  The  majority  of  successful  men 
started  in  active  life  with  no  capital  but  their  brains.  They 
established  themselves  by  gaining  the  confidence  of  the  in- 
vesting public,  and  many  utilize  their  good  names  as  their 
chief  financial  resource  throughout  their  careers. 

The  land  of  aU  civilized  countries  is  heavily  mortgaged. 
A  score  of  years  ago  the  mortgage  debt  in  the  TTnited  States 
was  35.5  per  cent  of  the  taxable  value  of  the  land.  In  France 
it  was  20  per  cent.  In  Prussia  rural  property  was  mortgaged 
Tip  to  nearly  40  per  cent  of  its  value.  These  are  typical  in- 
stances of  a  general  condition,  and  the  figures  of  today,  if 
compiled,  would  show  as  large  a  proportion.  In  the  United 
States  28.7  per  cent  of  the  farms  were  mortgaged  in  1890 ;  in 
1910  the  proportion  had  risen  to  36.8  per  cent. 

Through  the  varioiis  methods  of  credit  the  possibilities  of 
the  future  have  been  capitalized  and  drawn  upon  in  every 
conceivable  manner  for  the  benefit  of  present  enterprise.  But 
the  use  of  credit  vidthin  reasonable  limits  is  commendable  and 
should  be  encouraged  in  honest  and  capable  persons  who  have 
more  ideas  than  money  of  their  own.  A  man  who  borrows  to 
,set  himself  up  in  business,  to  buy  a  farm  or  increase  its 
yield,  to  cheapen  the  cost  of  the  growing  and  marketing  of 
crops,  or  for  any  other  productive  purpose,  does  exactly  what 
he  should  do,  because  the  transaction  enables  him  to  take 


CREDIT,   ITS   FOEMS   AND   USE  5 

advantage  of  his  opportunities  and  give  full  play  to  his  tal- 
ents, and  puts  him  in  the  way  of  doing  a  possible  good  to 
himself  and  family,  and  of  becoming  a  useful  member  of 
society  by  adding  to  the  nation's  wealth. 

The  machinery  for  credit  in  the  United  States  is  defective 
and  inadequate  from  the  point  of  view  of  agriculture.  There 
is  plenty  of  money,  it  is  true,  for  well-to-do  farmers  who  are 
able  to  meet  all  requirements  imposed  by  the  lender,  but  there 
are  no  means  whatever  for  granting  long-time  loans,  no 
arrangements,  except  in  a  few  local  and  special  cases,  for  pro- 
moting the  movement  of  the  people  back  to  the  land,  no  out- 
side sources  for  short-time  credit,  nor  any  system  whereby 
agriculture  may  have  first  use,  as  it  shoidd,  of  the  wealth  it 
creates  for  financing  itself.  About  the  only  facility  of  which 
farmers  avail  themselves  at  the  banks  is  the  straight  loan  on 
promissory  note.  They  depend  too  much  on  the  merchant 
to  carry  them  over  from  harvest  to  harvest,  and  on  this  indi- 
rect credit,  always  expensive,  of  instalment  purchases  and 
running  accounts  they  are  paying  excessive  interest  in  all 
localities  remote  from  financial  centers,  and  their  unfruc- 
tuous  debt  is  increasing  with  no  prospects  of  immediate 
reduction. 

The  farmers'  debt  in  1910,  as  estimated  by  the  United 
States  Department  of  Agriculture,  was  $250,000,000  on  store 
accounts,  $390,000,000  on  cotton  liens,  $450,000,000  on  other 
liens,  $417,000,000  miscellaneous,  $700,000,000  on  chattel 
mortgage,  and  $2,793,000i,000  on  real-estate  mortgage,  or  a 
total  of  $5,000,000,000.  The  Department  of  Agriculture  esti- 
mated in  1913  that  the  farmers'  debt  bears  an  average  rate 
of  interest  of  7.75  per  cent,  with  extremes  of  5.80  per  cent  in 
New  Hampshire  and  11.58  per  cent  in  Oklahoma.  Both  these 
estimates  are  admittedly  conservative  and  xmdoubtedly  fall 
below  the  truth  as  regards  liens,  unsecured  claims  and  interest 
rates.  Other  experts  have  found  instances  where  interest  was 
charged  at  the  rate  of  24  per  cent  per  annum  in  New  England 
and  40  per  cent  to  small  planters  in  the  cotton  states.  The 
fees  for  renewals  invariably  run  from  two  to  five  per  cent. 
The  incidental  costs  of  real-estate  mortgages  raise  the  rate 


6  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

a  point  or  so  above  the  written  rate.  Exorbitant  nsury  is 
often  concealed  in  running  accounts,  yet  over  one-half  of  the 
farmers  are  indebted  to  merchants  and  implement  dealers  in 
this  thriftless  form  of  credit.  Taking  these  facts  into  con- 
sideration, the  correct  figures  would  probably  exceed  $6,000,- 
000,000  for  the  debt  and  8.5  per  cent  for  the  average  interest 
rate. 

Although  stupendous  this  debt  does  not  necessarily  indi- 
cate an  unhealthy  condition.  Most  of  it  lies  in  the  newer 
sections  of  the  country  and  in  states  where  agriculture  is  most 
flourishing,  and  it  may  reasonably  be  inferred  that  it  was  con- 
tracted mainly  for  productive  purposes.  But  the  figures  have 
grown  rapidly  within  the  last  20  years  and  show  that  the  debt 
is  increasing  at  an  accelerating  rate  and  that  farmers  are 
paying  a  higher  rate  of  interest  than  is  justified  by  the  secur- 
ity which  they  can  offer.  This  total  debt  will  become  due 
within  the  next  five  years.  Kot  even  the  real-estate  mort- 
gages will  run  beyond  that  period.  But  all  will  not  be  repaid. 
That  would  be  impossible.  A  large  part  will  be  renewed  with 
commissions  and  additional  expenses,  and  wUl  remain  as  an 
accumulating  burden  upon  the  borrowers. 

New  debts  will  be  piled  upon  this  old  burden  because  the 
need  of  credit  will  expand  with  the  growth  of  the  country. 
In  1910  the  farms  of  the  United  States  comprised  878,798,325 
acres.  Less  than  one-half  of  this  area,  equal  in  extent  to 
about  12  states  of  the  size  of  Ohio,  is  improved,  and  produces 
only  a  portion  of  its  possible  yield.  Thousands  of  farms  lie 
abandoned  in  the  East,  millions  of  acres  are  still  untouched 
by  the  plow  in  the  unappropriated  public  lands,  and  vast 
areas  could  be  made  arable  by  irrigation  in  the  West,  or  by 
drainage  and  reclamation  along  the  coasts  and  iu  the  valleys 
of  the  large  rivers.  Since  not  one-fourth  of  the  land  is  under 
cultivation  and  its  production  is  far  below  the  possibilities, 
it  may  be  truthfully  said  that  the  surface  of  the  United  States 
has  only  been  scratched. 

But  the  work  of  replenishing  impoverished  soils,  opening 
up  new  fields,  and  stimulating  agriculture  in  all  its  branches 
cannot  be  long  deferred,  because  the  present  rate  of  increase 


CEEDIT,   ITS   rOEMS   AND  USB  7 

in  population  is  greater  than  the  rate  of  increase  in  the  means 
of  subsistence,  and  this  youngest  Eonong  the  nations  of  the 
earth  is  iu  danger  of  being  unable  to  feed  and  clothe  its  people 
in  spite  of  matchless  natural  resources.  The  farmers'  debt 
may  be  expected  to  augment  at  a  more  rapid  progression  than 
in  the  past,  but  no  one  can  foretell  the  size  it  will  attain  be- 
fore it  becomes  stationary  or  begins  to  decrease. 

The  enomlous  funds  which  agriculture  will  continue  to 
require  are  of  two  kinds.  The  first  is  the  fixed  capital  to  be 
sunk  permanently  or  for  a  long  period  iu  the  acquisition  and 
improvement  of  the  land  and  ia  the  purchase  of  equipment; 
the  second  is  the  circulating  capital  to  be  used  for  short 
periods  in  growing,  harvesting,  and  marketing  the  crops.  If 
correct  principles  were  followed,  the  borrowed  fixed  capital 
would  always  be  represented  by  the  real-estate  mortgages,  and 
the  repayment  gradually  made  out  of  the  annual  returns  from 
the  soil.  The  mortgage  would  then  be  as  near  an  unchanging 
security  as  it  is  possible  to  make  it,  while  a  prudential  limit 
would  be  set  against  excessive  borrowing.  Although  this  ar- 
rangement would  be  slow,  it  would  be  exceedingly  safe,  and 
it  would  also  leave  all  the  other  means  of  credit  for  the  cir- 
culating capital,  which  can  never  be  obtained  in  sufficient 
quantity  except  upon  securities  of  quick  and  easy  converti- 
bility. No  mortgage,  strictly  speaking,  is  a  real-estate  loan 
unless  it  be  intended  to  be  redeemed  out  of  the  land,  since 
otherwise  its  ultimate  recovery  depends  upon  a  personal  or 
other  kind  of  guaranty. 

Inasmuch  as  the  existing  system  fails  to  satisfy  aU  the 
credit  needs  of  agriculture,  the  question  arises  whether  the 
desired  reforms  should  be  worked  out  from  within,  or  brought 
about  by  starting  anew.  Six-sevenths  of  the  credit  now  ac- 
corded comes  from  local  sources.  The  remaining  one-seventh  is 
represented  by  the  real-estate  mortgages  held  by  life-insurance 
companies,  savings  banks,  and  individual  customers  of  a  few 
well-known  brokers.  These  lenders  usually  do  not  take  securi- 
ties exceeding  the  length  of  five  years.  Judging  from  facts, 
in  Europe  they  never  wiU  take  them.  Long-term  loans  can 
be  granted  only  in  connection  with  the  sale  of  debentures. 


8  ETJEAL   CREDITS 

The  farm-mortgage  debenture  was  never  given  a  fair  trial  in 
America.-  Even  its  name  has  fallen  into  disrepute,  and  it 
cannot  be  restored  to  grace  or  widely  used  for  drawing  money 
from  the  investing  public  until  regulations  are  prescribed  for 
its  issue  and  rules  for  appraising  property  are  standardized 
throughout  the  country.  Hence,  new  legislation  and  a  change 
of  business  methods  are  necessary  in  order  to  put  real-estate 
credit  on  a  proper  basis. 

As  to  short-term  loans  for  circulating  capital,  it  must  be 
borne  in  mind  that  the  chief  and  proper  use  of  the  sums 
borrowed  by  farmers  is  for  production,  for  the  creation  of 
somethiQg  that  did  not  exist  before.  Agriculture,  when  con- 
sidered from  year  to  year  and  over  extended  areas,  is  ia  its 
returns  the  surest  of  all  operations.  JSTevertheless,  there  are 
elements  of  risk  in  each  individual  case  until  the  product  is 
ready  for  the  market;  and  because  of  this  risk  agricultural 
credit  lacks  in  a  marked  degree  the  safety  ordinarily  required 
in  banking.  A  commercial  bank's  special  business  is  to  facili- 
tate the  exchange  of  things  of  definitely  ascertained  value 
already  in  existence.  Hence,  practically  all  the  service  that 
banks  of  this  character  can  render  agriculture  is  to  effect  the 
transfer  of  raw  material  after  it  has  been  created.  They 
cannot  grant  credit  on  the  potentiality  of  next  season's  crop 
any  more  than  they  can  take  in  security  the  uncaught  fish  of 
the  sea  or  the  ore  yet  to  be  extracted  from  the  mine. 

Furthermore,  the  shortest  period  needed  for  agricidture 
is  too  long  for  the  banks,  and  so  the  90-day  paper  of  the  mer- 
chant gets  the  preference  over  the  six-month  or  one-year 
paper  of  the  farmer.  As  a  result,  the  major  portion  of  the 
farmers'  credit  is  not  bankable  under  the  present  system,  and 
only  a  comparatively  small  amount  of  their  paper  reaches  the 
outside  world.  Consequently,  when  they  wish  to  realize  upon 
their  credit  to  its  fullest  extent,  the  farmers  must  pay  a  pre- 
mium for  the  risk  incurred,  besides  the  highest  interest 
charged  ia  their  immediate  vicinity.  A  new  system  to  be 
added  to  the  old  is  necessary  to  rectify  this  trouble  also,  in 
spite  of  the  powers  recently  granted  to  national  banks  by  the 
Federal  Eeserve  Act  of  1913. 


CREDIT,   ITS   FORMS   AND   USE  9 

This  act  provides  that  any  national  banking  association 
not  situated  in  a  central  reserve  city  may  make  loans  secured 
by  improved  and  imencumbered  farm  land,  situated  within  its 
federal  reserve  district,  but  no  such  loan  shall  be  made  for 
a  longer  time  than  five  years  nor  for  an  amount  exceeding  50 
per  cent  of  the  actual  value  of  the  property  offered  as  security. 
Such  a  bank  may  make  such  loans  in  an  aggregate  sum  equal 
to  35  per  cent  of  its  capital  and  surplus  or  to  one-third  of  its 
time  deposits.  Reserve  banks  may  rediscount  notes,  drafts 
and  bOls  of  exchange  issued  or  drawn  for  agricultural  pur- 
poses or  based  on  livestock,  provided  that  the  maturity  does 
not  exceed  six  months  or  the  total  does  not  exceed  in  amount 
the  percentage  of  its  capital  to  be  ascertained  and  fixed  by 
the  Federal  Reserve  Board. 

These  provisions  impose  no  obligation.  Experience  alone 
will  determine  the  effect  thereof,  but  it  is  probable  that  the 
federal  reserve  banks  will  proceed  along  customary  lines  and 
keep  every  possible  dollar  of  their  capital,  deposits  and  sur- 
plus in  quickly  maturing  and  easily  convertible  assets. 

Agricultural  wealth  and  production  in  the  United  States 
are  greater  than  in  any  other  country.  The  figures  are  stu- 
pendous. In  1910  farm  property  was  valued  at  $40,991,449,- 
090,  of  which  $28,475,674,169  was  in  land.  If  this  capital 
were  mobilized  the  credit  needs  of  farmers  could  be  supplied 
for  all  time  to  come.  The  annual  returns  were  $8,417,000,- 
000.  This  is  more  than  suflScient  to  finance  a  banking  system 
for  the  exclusive  use  of  the  farmers.  Mobilization  can  be 
accomplished,  however,  only  through  institutions  capable  of 
lengthening  the  period  of  loans,  allowing  repayment  by 
amortization,  and  able  to  make  heavy  and  constant  sales  of 
debentures  issued  against  the  mortgages  taken.  As  regards 
short-term  credit,  the  best  banking  system  ever  devised  for 
enabling  farmers  to  utilize  their  own  funds  and  revenues  for 
their  own  purposes  is  a  cooperative  system. 

The  object  of  the  movement  which  has  been  set  on  foot 
to  improve  farm  credit  facilities  is  the  introduction  of  these 
principles  and  practices.  Europe  furnishes  the  best  models 
to  be  studied.     But  this  does  not  mean  that  all  European 


10  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

countries  have  established  perfect  and  completely  adequate 
systems  for  farmers  and  landowners.  The  case  is  quite  other- 
wise. Germany  is  the  only  country  in  which  the  ideal  has  been 
approached,  und  much  remains  to  be  done  there.  All  the 
other  agricultural  nations,  however,  have  made  considerable 
progress.  Hence,  a  study  of  the  work  which  has  been  done 
and  of  the  results  obtained  in  Europe  will  assist  the  solution 
of  the  problems  arising  in  the  reorganization  of  land  and 
rural  credit  ia  the  United  States. 


CHAPTBE  II 

SPECIAIi   PRIVILEGE   AND   STATE    AID 

Substitution  of  Companies  for  Individual  Money  Lenders. — ^Break-up 
of  Feudal  System  in  Europe. — Special  Privileges  for  Determin- 
ing Titles. — ^Necessities  of  European  Peasants. — Two  European 
Classes  of  Organizations  for  Lending  Money. — ^American  Need 
of  Long-term,  Beducible  Loans. 

The  organization  of  land  credit  means  the  substitution  of 
specifically  designed  bodies  in  place  of  iadividuals  as  money 
lenders.  These  bodies  cannot  operate  with  safety,  convenience 
and  profit  unless  they  have  infallible  rules  for  proving  titles 
and  determining  the  value  of  land,  and  quick  and  cheap 
methods  of  legal  procedure  for  recovering  loans.  Nor  can 
they  do  much  good  without  safeguards  for  investors  and  re- 
strictions against  thriftless  borrowing.  At  the  inception  of 
land-credit  institutions  on  the  continent  of  Europe,  special 
privileges  were  granted  for  their  encouragement  and  protec- 
tion. All  land-credit  institutions  created  before  1860  were 
endowed  with  extraordinary  rights  in  respect  to  administra- 
tive and  judicial  matters  or  accorded  fiscal  or  financial  favors 
and  exemptions ;  and  the  tendency  of  legislation  today  is  still 
towards  governmental  subsidy  and  control  where  the  bor- 
rowers are  exclusively  farmers  or  small  holders. 

In  tracing  the  origin  of  this  intervention  of  the  state,  the 
troubles  arising  out  of  the  breaking  up  of  the  feudal  system 
must  not  be  overlooked.  This  system  prevailed  throughout 
Europe  from  the  eighth  century  down  to  modem  times.  It 
remained  in  Russia  until  1861;  its  last  vestiges  were  not 
stamped  out  in  Germany  until  1851.  It  was  based  in  the 
begirming  entirely  on  militarism.  The  land  was  allotted  to 
the  nobility  in  immense  tracts  on  condition  of  furnishing  sup- 

11 


12  EURAL   CREDITS 

plies  of  troops  or  money  to  the  king  for  carrying  on  war. 
Each  nobleman  usually  divided  aU  his  estate  not  needed  for 
the  manor  into  three  parts.  One  part  was  leased  to  knights 
in  return  for  military  service,  another  to  civilians  in  return 
for  farm  labor  and  produce,  and  the  remainder  was  left  as 
commons  for  all.  In  addition,  numerous  small  plots  were 
occupied  by  persons  who  were  obliged  to  act  as  menials  or  to 
hold  themselves  in  readiness  to  do  various  kinds  of  unpaid 
work.  The  knights  and  civilians  sublet  their  fiefs  in  the 
same  way.  The  rights  and  duties  under  the  system  were 
hereditary,  passing  from  father  to  son.  No  one  could  transfer 
or  evade  them,  or  change  his  residence  without  consent  of 
his  superior.  The  farming  and  laboring  classes  were  serfs, 
or  slaves  boTind  to  the  soil,  with  no  political  rights  whatever 
and  very  few  civil  rights  which  their  masters  could  not  dis- 
regard with  impunity. 

Under  feudalism  all  the  land  was  owned  in  theory  by  the 
Crown.  Hence,  when  kings  realized  that  this  antiquated  sys- 
tem, which  had  outgrown  its  usefulness,  interfered  with  their 
own  powers  and  blocked  the  progress  of  their  people,  their 
advisers  found  plenty  of  arguments  to  justify  their  course  in 
breaking  it  up.  On  the  other  hand,  a  sense  of  justice  made 
them  feel  responsible  for  the  consequences  of  the  change  and 
urged  them  to  strive  to  adjust  the  old  to  the  new  order  of 
things.  Feudalism,  however,  was  not  abolished  by  one  stroke 
of  the  pen,  nor  was  each  step  taken  in  the  same  way.  The 
march  of  events  was  often  attended  by  periods  of  violence  and 
aggression  when  vested  rights  were  utterly  ignored,  and 
many  statutes,  with  long  intervals  between  them,  were  en- 
acted in  every  state  before  the  complete  eradication  of  the 
system.  Generally  the  high  and  discretionary  powers  were 
taken  first  from  the  nobles.  Next,  freedom  was  given  to  the 
serfs,  and  later  on  the  privilege  to  own  and  sell  property. 
Finally,  executive  and  legislative  acts  were  promulgated  re- 
garding the  land  itself.  In  some  states  the  nobility  was  arbi- 
trarily despoiled  of  a  portion  or  all  of  their  holdings;  in 
others,  compensation  was  provided  for  the  confiscation  by 
allowing  the  hereditary  occupants  to  acquire  the  fee  only  by 


SPECIAL  PEIVILEGE  AND  STATE  AID        13 

conmniting  the  servitudes,  tithes,  dues  and  corvee  into  per- 
petual rents  or  annuities  for  definite  periods. 

The  laws  were  often  conflicting,  obscure  and  defective,  for 
they  dealt  with  the  evolution  of  a  new  and  untried  social 
condition  wherein  the  rights  of  men  were  to  rise  above  the 
rights  of  property,  and  citizenship  was  to  be  detached  from 
the  ownership  of  land.  A  tangle  of  court  decisions  added  to 
the  confusion.  It  was  not  until  long  after  real  estate  was 
capable  of  being  held  by  plebeians  and  made  freely  alienable 
and  mortgageable  by  simple  agreement  that  the  title  could 
be  transferred  without  danger  or  trouble.  This  was  finally 
brought  about  by  requiring  the  instruments  to  be  filed  and 
recorded  in  public  registration  oflSces  in  order  to  be  valid 
against  third  parties.  But  in  some  European  countries  even 
at  present  certain  estates  cannot  be  assigned  or  encumbered, 
while  hidden  claims  are  likely  to  appear  to  defeat  the  title 
of  an  ordinary  purchaser  in  spite  of  every  precaution.  The 
ease  and  safety  with  which  real  estate  may  be  disposed  of 
within  a  few  hours  in  most  of  the  American  states  was 
possible  nowhere  in  Europe  until  a  comparatively  recent 
date. 

Special  privileges  for  determining  titles,  however,  have 
not  been  bestowed  by  all  European  nations.  Germany  and 
France  are  almost  alone  in  this  respect,  and  the  privileges 
were  granted  there  perhaps  because  the  effort  to  organize 
land  credit  began  before  the  idea  of  enforcing  registration  of 
titles  and  of  reforming  mortgage  laws  by  general  legislation 
was  worked  out.  Nor,  except  in  a  few  instances,  have  special 
methods  been  prescribed  for  appraising  property.  'Jhe  estima- 
tion of  values  has  been  left  usually  to  private  discretion,  and 
the  borrower  and  lender  have  been  safeguarded  by  Hmiting  the 
amount  of  the  loan  by  rules  fixed  by  general  law.  Special 
privilege  and  state  aid  to  facilitate  the  raising  of  money,  how- 
ever, have  been  a  common  practice.  Many  governments  as- 
sisted and  even  created  institutions  whose  purpose  was  to 
compensate  dispossessed  lords  or  supply  them  with  capital  to 
hire  labor  in  place  of  the  liberated  serfs,  or  to  furnish  these 
f reedmen  with  the  means  to  purchase  farms ;  and  this  plan  is 


14  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

still  being  followed  to  encourage  young  men  to  go  back  to 
the  land  or  to  remain  upon  it. 

But  wherever  this  intervention  occurs  it  is  motivated  by 
the  old  feudal  notion  which  led  kings  to  believe  that  the  land 
and  its  occupants  belonged  to  them  and  should  be  subject  to 
their  particular  care.  As  the  rights  and  duties  dropped  away 
from  the  lords,  they  passed  over  to  the  kings  and  finally 
lodged  in  constitutional  governments.  Feudalism  was  fre- 
quently replaced  by  paternalism.  England,  Sweden,  Norway, 
Germany  and  some  of  the  flourishing  small  states  did  not 
develop  along  this  Une,  but  all  the  other  large  agricultural 
nations  took  this  bent,  and  treated  the  agricultural  classes 
as  dependent  wards,  if  they  gave  them  any  friendly  considera- 
tion at  aU. 

Literature  teems  with  stories  of  the  ignorance,  poverty 
and  degradation  of  the  continental  European  peasants  up  to 
a  half -century  ago.  Masses  of  them  are  still  so  poor  that  they 
do  most  of  their  work  by  hand,  carry  their  produce  to  market 
on  their  backs  or  in  carts  drawn  by  themselves  or  their  wives, 
and  are  forced  to  use  every  miserable  little  economy  to  keep 
body  and  soul  together.  To  call  an  American  farmer  a 
peasant  would  be  to  insult  him,  although  the  equivalents  of 
the  word  in  foreign  languages  convey  no  offensive  meaning. 
This  shows  what  agricultural  conditions  in  Europe  are  as 
viewed  by  American  eyes.  The  majority  of  peasants  are  land- 
less or  own  plots  too  small  to  be  mortgaged  and  have  no  chance 
to  obtain  more  on  their  own  standing  alone.  Hence,  they  are 
able  to  get  real-estate  credit  only  by  cooperation  or  from  in- 
stitutions assisted  or  privileged  by  the  state. 

The  feudal  system  did  not  gain  foothold  on  American 
soil,  so  the  United  States  has  never  had  a  complicated  variety 
of  tenures  and  gradation  of  ranks,  the  removal  of  which  called 
for  severe  remedies.  The  principles  of  equality  which  pre- 
sided at  the  nation's  birth  have  been  constantly  manifested  by 
avoiding  special  and  using  general  laws  wherever  it  has  been 
possible  to  do  so.  Special  legislation,  either  for  individuals  or 
classes,  would  now  be  revolutionary  and  also  would  deaden 
the  spirit  of  those  who  should  rely  upon  it.    The  American 


SPECIAL  PEIVILEGE  AND  STATE  AID       15 

farmers  are  better  men  than  the  European  peasantry.  Fur- 
thermore they  are  the  most  independent  and  self-reliant  part 
of  the  country's  population.  It  does  not  seem  likely  that 
they  wiU  demand  privileges  and  special  favors  devised  for 
conditions  which  have  no  parallel  in  this  coimtry,  and  which 
would  do  them  in  the  long  run  more  harm  than  good. 

The  two  classes  of  bodies  substituted  for  individuals  as 
money  lenders  in  Europe  have  as  prime  object  either  the  bene- 
fit of  borrowers  or  the  profit  of  stockholders  and  investors. 
The  first  class  has  been  the  more  favored  by  state  aid  and 
special  privilege.  It  includes  the  landschafts,  similar  asso- 
ciations of  borrowers,  public  land  banks,  banks  operating  with 
funds  or  on  the  guaranty  of  the  state,  besides  governmental 
institutions  or  bureaus  handling  funds  appropriated  for  some 
specific  purpose  relating  to  land.  The  second  class  comprises 
joint-stock  mortgage  companies,  banks  with  land-credit  de- 
partments, and  concerns  which  take  mortgages  simply  for 
their  own  investment.  Some  of  these  also  have  been  specially 
privileged  and  aided  by  the  state. 

The  provisions  in  the  laws  and  organic  acts  under  which 
these  numerous  institutions  were  created  require  detailed 
description  to  be  understood;  many  of  them,  however,  would 
serve  no  useful  purpose  in  the  United  States,  siace  their  place 
is  amply  filled  already.  The  American  trust  companies,  sav- 
ings banks  and  other  banks  chartered  by  the  states,  and  life- 
insurance  companies  surpass  the  corresponding  European  in- 
stitutions in  extending  real-estate  credit  to  farmers,  while 
the  methods  employed  for  reclaiming  and  settling  the  arid 
regions  iu  the  West,  show  a  capacity  for  solving  problems 
peculiar  to  locality  equal  at  least  to  that  of  the  land-improve- 
ment and  colonization  projects  of  any  European  government. 
From  the  Ordinance  of  1787  which  opened  up  the  Northwest 
Territory,  declared  by  Daniel  Webster  to  be  as  great  as  the 
Constitution  itself,  down  to  the  Federal  Eeclamation  Act  and 
the  drainage  laws  of  some  of  the  states,  American  government 
has  displayed  an  originality  and  effectiveness  of  design  in  the 
use  of  public  resources,  power  and  credit  for  individual  wel- 
fare which  eliminate  the  necessity  of  foreign  models. 


16  EURAL   CREDITS 

State  aid  as  well  as  special  privilege  is  such  a  predomi- 
nating feature  in  the  larger  and  more  active  credit  institu- 
tions of  some  of  the  paternalistic  nations  of  Europe  that  their 
results  are  artificial  and  do  not  afford  a  criterion  by  vrhich 
to  judge  the  actual  credit  value  of  land — a  poiut  to  be  borne 
in  mind  in  examiniug  their  systems  of  organization.  The 
interest  rate  on  a  mortgage  made  from  free  or  cheap  money 
advanced  by  the  state,  or  raised  by  the  sale  of  bonds  guaran- 
teed by  the  state  or  issued  by  an  institution  connected  with 
the  state,  reflects  ultimately  the  public  standing  and  credit 
of  that  state,  and  naturally  is  often  low.  The  chief  if  not  the 
only  lessons  to  be  learned  by  a  study  of  European  land-credit 
systems  are  the  wonderful  benefit  to  farmers  of  unrecallable 
long-term  reducible  loans,  and  the  ease  and  abundance  in 
which  money  may  be  obtained  for  them  by  the  issue  of  de- 
bentures or  mortgage-bonds  secured  either  by  the  solidarity  of 
^oups  of  landowners,  or  by  the  assets  of  a  company  officially 
supervised  and  properly  managed. 


CHAPTEE  III 

LONG-TEEM    LOANS    AND    AMOETIZATION 

Definition. — Four  Methods  of  Extinguishing  a  Loan. — ^History  of 
Amortization  Plan. — Two  Advantages  of  Amortizable  Loans  Ee- 
payable  by  Annuities. — ^Relation  of  Value  of  Land  to  Loans. — 
Amortization  Impossible  for  Ordinary  Money-lenders. — Absolute 
Safety  Necessary  for  Bonds  of  Amortization  Companies. — De- 
bentures the  Key  to  the  System. 

A  LONG  TEEM  foT  real-estate  credit  in  Europe  is  any 
period  of  from  ten  to  seventy-five  or  more  years.  A  mort- 
gage-bond is  a  promissory  note  of  the  maker,  secured  by  desig- 
nated mortgages  held  in  trust.  A  debenture  is  secured,  not  by 
designated  mortgages,  but  only  by  a  floating  charge  against 
the  assets  of  the  maker.  It  may  be  a  promissory  note  and 
mature  at  a  certain  date,  but  when  used  for  long-term  opera- 
tions, it  is  generally  made  in  the  naked  form  of  a  certified 
acknowledgment  of  indebtedness,  having  no  fixed  time  for 
maturity  of  the  principal,  or  else  calculated  to  run  for  the 
length  of  the  loan  against  which  it  is  issued,  and  withdraw- 
able by  lot  or  at  the  will  of  the  maker  alone;  until  so  re- 
called it  does  not  entitle  the  holder  to  any  right  except  the 
receipt  of  interest. 

There  are  four  methods  besides  payment  in  full  of  extiu- 
guishing  a  reducible  or  amortizable  loan.  The  first  is  by 
equal  instalments.  Under  this  method  the  borrower  obli- 
gates himself  to  pay  a  specified  portion  of  the  principal  to- 
gether with  the  interest  annually,  semi-annually  or  quarterly. 
For  example,  for  a  loan  of  $4,000  payable  within  20  years, 
he  may  pay  40  semi-annual  instalments  of  $100  each,  plus 
of  course  the  interest  due  on  remaining  principal ;  or  he  may 
make  15  semi-annual  payments  of  $50  each,  followed  by  10 

17 


18  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

of  $100  eachj  and  finally  by  15  of  $150  each,  thus  reserving 
the  larger  instalments  for  later  years  when  the  interest 
charges  become  smaller. 

The  second  method  is  that  employed  by  the  German  land- 
sehafts.  Here  the  borrower  obligates  himself  to  pay  the 
interest  on  the  full  original  amount  of  his  loan,  and,  in  addi- 
tion, one-half  of  one  per  cent  or  more  per  annum  as  long  as 
it  runs.  All  of  this  extra  payment  not  needed  for  expenses 
is  put  into  a  sinking  fund  and  carefully  invested  to  redeem  the 
debentures  given  to  him  for  his  mortgage.  Since  the  accumu- 
lations to  his  credit  depend  upon  savings  and  profits  made  by 
the  landschaft,  there  is  no  way  of  foretelling  when  the  debt 
wiU  be  cancelled. 

The  third  is  the  method  of  the  Austrian  and  German 
savings  banks.  Here  also  the  borrower  pays  interest  on 
the  full  amount  of  his  loan,  plus  one-half  of  one  per  cent  or 
more  per  annum  as  long  as  it  runs.  The  excess  is  credited  to 
him  as  on  a  deposit  account  drawing  interest.  When  this 
account  and  the  loan  account  balance  one  another  his  debt  is 
cancelled.  The  rate  paid  by  the  bank  is  always  lower  than 
that  paid  by  the  borrower  and  is  subject  to  frequent  changes ; 
hence,  as  in  the  landschafts,  the  date  of  the  extinction  of 
the  debt  cannot  be  fixed  in  advance. 

The  fourth  is  the  French  method  generally  called  true 
amortization.  Here  the  borrower  executes  a  contract,  secured 
by  mortgage,  to  pay  annuities  to  the  company  in  consideration 
of  the  sum  loaned.  The  annuity  which  must  be  paid  to 
amortize  this  sum  is  determined  by  the  length  of  the  credit 
and  the  agreed  rate  of  interest;  it  remains  level  during  the 
entire  period  of  the  loan  and  is  usually  paid  in  semi-annual 
instalments.  When  a  payment  is  made,  the  company  deducts 
therefrom  the  interest  due  itself  and  applies  the  remainder  to 
reduce  the  principal  of  the  loan.  Hence  as  time  progresses 
the  deductions  for  interest  grow  smaller  and  smaller  and  the 
portions  available  for  the  principal  correspondingly  larger 
until  the  debt  is  completely  extinguished.  For  example,  on 
a  $1,000  mortgage  loan  for  30  years  at  4.30  per  cent  per  an- 
num the  semi-annual  annuity  is  $29.82218.    In  the  second 


LONG-TERM   LOANS   AND   AMORTIZATION      19 

half  of  the  fifth  year  $19.74399  of  this  annuity  is  used  for 
interest  and  $10.07819  for  the  reduction  of  the  principal.  In 
the  fifteenth  year  the  larger  portion,  $15.42233,  is  for  the 
first  time  set  aside  for  the  principal,  and  thereafter  this  por- 
tion rapidly  increases  in  size.  In  the  twentieth  year  it  be- 
comes $19.07803 ;  in  the  twenty-fifth  year  $23.60029,  and  in 
the  thirtieth  or  last  year  all  except  $0.62765  of  the  annuity 
is  applied  on  the  principal,  and  nothing  remains  to  be  paid. 

It  is  commonly  stated  that  the  repayment  of  mortgage 
loans  by  amortization  was  devised  by  a  bank  in  Stockholm  in 
1754,  but  the  germ  of  the  idea  is  found  in  practices  which 
preceded  that  date  by  many  years.  Reference  has  been  made 
already  to  the  commuting  of  the  rights  of  masters  against 
serfs  to  annual  dues  at  the  end  of  feudalism.  There  were 
other  reasons  for  creating  such  encumbrances.  Contracts  for 
perpetual  or  long  rents  were  entered  into  as  a  means  of  evad- 
ing the  law  and  effecting  the  transfers  of  lands  which  could 
not  be  legally  alienated.  These  contracts  were  given  also,  in 
satisfaction  of  debts  or  for  the  recovery  of  loans,  to  the  Church 
and  devout  Christians  whose  sensitive  consciences  would  not 
allow  them  to  act  in  the  open  as  money  lenders  because  of 
their  belief  that  all  interest  was  sinful  usury  and  forbidden 
by  the  Bible.  Hence,  the  groundwork  for  the  establishment  of 
amortization  in  Europe  was  well  laid;  its  adoption  and  devel- 
opment, nevertheless,  were  exceedingly  slow. 

From  Sweden  the  idea  passed  over  to  England  and  thence 
back  to  the  Continent.  Erederick  the  Great  seems  to  have 
had  an  early  knowledge  of  it,  for  he  said  at  a  meeting  of  the 
landowners  of  Brandenburg  on  January  18,  1776:  "I  wiU 
gladly  let  you  have  3,400,000  thalers  ($2,427,600)  at  four  per 
cent.  This  wiU  give  you  a  fond  d'amortissement."  George  III, 
who  was  the  common  sovereign  of  Great  Britain  and  Hanover, 
had  a  clear  understanding  of  the  principles  of  amortization. 
The  charter  which  he  granted  to  a  credit  association  at  Cella 
for  the  nobles  of  Liineburg,  provided  that  the  loans  should 
be  repayable  by  annuities  of  not  more  than  five  per  cent,  out 
of  which  one  and  seven-tenths  per  cent  for  the  first  five  years 
and  one-eighth  of  one  per  cent  thereafter  should  be  placed  in 


20  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  sinking  fund.  Two  per  cent  out  of  the  annuities  of  new 
members  could  be  so  used  for  the  first  five  years.  If  the 
association  had  to  issue  debentures  bearing  more  than  three 
per  cent  the  higher  rate  coxdd  be  obtained  only  by  "prolonging 
the  amortization  period"  of  the  borrowers,  a  phrase  which 
shows  unmistakably  an  intention  to  apply  correct  principles. 
The  first  actual  use  of  these  principles  on  the  Continent,  how- 
ever, was  by  the  credit  association  founded  for  the  Grand 
Duchy  of  Posen,  June  28,  1821.  The  debentures  of  this 
concern  were  subject  to  an  amortization  of  41  years,  and  the 
borrowing  members  in  consequence  paid  one  per  cent  for  re- 
demption in  addition  to  the  four  per  cent  on  their  mortgages 
and  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  for  expenses.  All  the  old 
German  landschafts  evolved  their  methods  and  put  them  in 
general  practice  in  1839  or  thereafter,  and  Prance  began  upon 
her  method  in  1852. 

Two  general  advantages  inhere  in  amortizable  loans  of  the 
fourth  kind,  repayable  by  annuities.  The  accumulation  of 
the  fractional  payments  builds  up  a  sinking  fund  which  makes 
any  debentures  issued  against  the  mortgages  more  secure  as 
time  progresses,  and  assures  their  final  redemption.  The 
same  process  likewise  enables  the  borrower  to  utilize  his  small 
savings  for  the  reduction  of  his  debt,  and  practically  to  adjust 
its  size  and  length  and  the  amount  of  his  annual  dues  to  the 
capacity  of  the  land  and  himself  for  repayment.  The  latter 
advantage  was  the  aim  of  the  oldest  institutions.  The  nine- 
teenth century  dawned  in  Europe  upon  a  land  overwhelmed 
with  debt,  which  continued  to  increase.  In  France,  in  1852, 
interest  and  taxes  were  absorbing  two-fifths  of  the  revenue 
of  the  soil,  and  France  was  in  no  worse  plight  than  her  neigh- 
bors. Farmers  and  landowners  were  not  seeking  new  loans, 
for  they  had  stretched  their  credit  to  the  limit.  Creditors  and 
claimants  had  placed  them  on  the  verge  of  bankruptcy. 
What  they  wanted  was  some  way  to  convert  the  existing  in- 
debtedness into  obligations  with  more  equitable  and  tolerable 
terms.  The  nature  of  this  necessity  led  directly  to  the  long- 
term  loan,  amortization  and  the  debenture.  The  making  of 
safe  and  convenient  securities  for  investors  was  a  secondary 


LONG-TERM   LOANS   AND   AMORTIZATION      31 

matter  which  received  attention  later  on.  The  main  objects 
of  the  European  governments  in  the  organization  of  real- 
estate  credit  until  after  the  middle  of  the  century  was  to 
relieve  debtors,  to  pass  their  burden  on  to  future  generations 
if  need  be,  and  have  it  paid  off  gradually  by  the  slow  returns 
of  the  soil. 

Land  owned  for  use  by  the  proprietor  is  worth  all  its  net 
returns ;  held  for  speetdation  or  for  some  reason  of  sentiment 
or  fancy,  it  may  be  estimated  by  ether  standards  at  a  far 
greater  price ;  but  considered  merely  as  security  for  a  loan,  it 
can  be  valued  only  by  a  portion  of  the  returns,  or  what  re- 
mains after  paying  tazes,  making  repairs  and  allowing  the 
farmer  enough  to  live  on.  If  the  farmer's  share  be  increased 
so  as  to  afford  him  a  fair  compensation,  the  remaiuder  would 
be  proportionately  smaller  and  practically  would  correspond 
with  the  rent.  Now  the  rent  in  old,  thickly  settled  commimi- 
ties  is  no  more  than  three  per  cent  of  the  selling  price  of 
land.  Hence,  political  economists  like  Adam  Smith  and  Jean 
Sismondi  contended  that  capital  sunk  in  the  purchase  of  real 
estate  can  never  be  recovered,  because  its  returns  are  sufficient 
to  pay  only  the  interest  at  the  lowest  rates.  This  theory  of 
course  coiild  be  true  in  practice  only  for  a  loan  which  equals 
the  full  selling  price  of  the  mortgaged  land  or  exhausts  all 
its  credit  value.  A  smaller  loan  may  be  made  at  a  high  in- 
terest rate  and  with  quick  maturity  since  it  has  all  the  returns 
and  the  security  of  a  safe  margin  to  fall  back  upon. 

These  opinions  nevertheless  carried  great  weight  and  left 
their  stamp  on  the  early  legislation.  The  annual  sum  which 
the  German  landschafts  required  a  borrower  to  pay  into  the 
sinking  fund  averaged  only  a  fraction  of  one  per  cent  of  the 
principal  of  the  loan.  This  provision  is  still  in  force,  and  in 
consequence  the  members  of  the  landschafts  are  mostly  per- 
sons who  wish  large  loans  and  give  mortgages  which  cover 
their  entire  properties.  The  maximum  for  Ueensed  land-credit 
companies  in  France  was  put  originally  at  two  per  cent,  but 
eventually  it  was  changed  by  an  amendment  which  forbids 
the  borrower  to  obligate  himself  to  pay  a  larger  annuity  than 
the  revenues  of  the  mortgaged  property. 


23  EUEAL   CEBDITS 

The  French  restriction  proved  to  be  better  than  the  Ger- 
man because,  while  protecting  the  borrower  from  the  tempta- 
tion of  entering  into  a  contract  to  pay  back  a  loan  faster  than 
he  can  make  it  or  its  equivalent  out  of  the  soil,  it  permitted 
him  to  utilize  the  entire  credit  value  of  his  holdings  either 
for  a  large  long-term  loan  or  for  a  smaller  short-term  loan 
with  higher  interest  and  dues  in  case  of  an  urgent  necessity. 
This  freedom  of  action  resulted  in  the  use  of  various  combi- 
nations of  interest  rates  and  loan  periods,  and  gave  full  play 
for  the  first  time  to  all  the  possibilities  of  amortization, 
"without  which,"  says  Eoyer,  "every  real-estate  credit  system 
is  an  incomplete  and  fragile  scaffold,  deceiving  the  public  and 
endangering,  the  welfare  of  any  nation  relying  on  it." 

But  this  amortization,  so  needful  and  beneficial  for  farm- 
ers, is  practically  an  impossible  operation  for  ordinary  money 
lenders.  No  individuals  and  but  few  companies  can  afford  to 
tie  up  their  capital  and  take  it  back  in  driblets  as  it  is  re- 
funded bit  by  bit  out  of  the  earnings  or  savings  from  the  soil 
during  a  long  series  of  years.  The  only  type  of  concern  which 
can  accommodate  agriculture  in  this  way  on  a  large  scale  is 
one  authorized  and  able  to  issue  and  sell  debentures  and 
thereby  to  recover  immediately  the  money  so  sunk  regardless 
of  the  length  of  the  loans.  Furthermore,  the  concern  must 
be  large  and  so  organized  and  managed  that  the  annuities 
wiU  flow  in  suflScient  volume  to  form  fairly  large  amounts 
for  profitable  investment,  and  that  the  sinking  fund  thus 
accumulated  be  guarded  as  securely  as  the  reserves  of  a  life- 
insurance  company,  for  the  retirement  of  outstanding  deben- 
tures and  the  liquidation  of  its  borrowers'  loans.  These  an- 
nuities, less  the  interest  charges,  should  be  placed  at  each 
payment  with  their  earnings  to  the  credit  of  the  borrower's 
account  in  the  sinking  fund,  so  that  compound  interest  may 
run  in  his  favor  against  the  company  or  against  bondholders 
in  the  companjr's  favor.  In  this  way  the  borrower  never  has 
actually  to  repay  the  full  amount  of  his  loan,  or  else  he  may 
get  the  lowest  interest  rate  on  it. 

Long-term  operations  may  endure  beyond  the  lives  of  the 
contracting  parties,  and  consequently  investors  will  not  buy 


LONG-TEEM   LOANS   AND  AMORTIZATION     33 

the  bonds  of  an  amortization  house  nor  landowners  enter  into 
annuity  contracts  with  it  unless  they  be  assured  of  the  abso- 
lute safety  of  the  transactions.  There  must  be  complete  con- 
fidence and  strength  and  stability  approaching  permanence 
for  such  an  institution  to  continue  in  business  extensively. 
For  this  reason,  besides  being  specially  privileged  in  some 
countries,  amortization  houses  are  subject  to  more  rigorous 
regulations  and  restrictions  than  ordinary  money  lenders, 
with  the  view  of  safeguarding  the  rights  even  of  generations 
to  come  and  also  of  keeping  the  door  of  the  money  market 
continually  open  to  them.  Most  of  these  regulations  relate  to 
the  debenture,  the  key  to  the  success  of  the  system,  which,  as 
drawn  in  Europe,  has  never  been  used  in  the  United  States 
in  real-estate  credit. 


CHAPTER  IV 

DEBENTURES 

Land  as  the  Basis  for  Issue  of  Paper  Money. — ^History  of  Experi- 
ments in  England,  Prussia,  France,  and  the  Colonies. — ^Land 
Good  as  Such  Basis  Only  if  Owned  by  Government. — ^Not  Pos- 
sible as  Basis  for  Bank  Loans. — Characteristics  of  Deben- 
tures. 

The  form  and  use  of  the  debenture  grew  out  of  the  old 
ideas  of  making  the  land  a  basis  for  the  issue  of  paper  money. 
Some  of  these  ideas  left  lasting  impress  on  history.  In  the 
middle  of  the  seventeenth  century,  when  commerce  in  Eng- 
land was  awakening  and  inland  bills  and  promissory  notes 
came  into  general  use  (1645),  the  need  was  felt  for  a  bank 
to  act  as  a  clearing  house  for  the  nation.  There  were  banks 
on  the  Contiaent  which  issued  notes  against  coin  deposited  in 
their  vaults.  English  financiers,  however,  suggested  that 
goods  and  merchandise  also  be  adopted  as  a  basis  for  currency. 
There  soon  followed  the  argument  that  land,  being  stable,  im- 
perishable, and  not  capable  of  being  stolen  or  removed,  would 
be  even  better  than  coin  or  goods  and  merchandise  for  this 
purpose,  and  an  active  propaganda  was  started  for  the  estab- 
lishment of  land  banks  which  should  emit  notes.  The  discus- 
sion ended  m  the  founding  of  the  Bank  of  England  in  1694. 
This  institution,  however,  did  not  meet  with  the  immediate 
success  promised,  and  the  agitation  for  land  credit  was  re- 
vived and  conducted  with  such  vigor  that  Parliament  incor- 
porated the  Land  Bank  in  1695  and  the  National  Land  Bank 
in  1696.  The  latter  institution  did  not  materialize  because  of 
the  inability  of  its  promoters  to  raise  capital.  The  cause  of 
the  disappearance  of  the  Land  Bank  is  not  known,  but  during 
its  short  existence  it  issued  bills  and  notes  which  were  given 

24 


DEBENTrRES  35 

and  received  as  currency,  and  which  were  preferred  to  specie 
by  many.    Their  form  was  as  follows : 

This  bill  pursuant  to  the  settlement  of  the  Land  Bank  en- 
rolled in  Chanceiy,  Anno  Dom.  1695,  doth  charge  one  hundred 
pound  value  of  register  secured  upon  lands,  rents  and  estates, 
entered  in  Libro  A  Wo.  1,  and  the  stock  of  moneys  and  funds 
of  insurance  annexed  to  said  bank,  with  the  payment  of  one 
hundred  pounds  and  interest,  etc.  (or  without  interest)  to  John 
Doe,  etc. 

By  Order  of  the  Trustee  and  Managers. 

In  1705  John  Law,  subsequently  famed  for  the  "Missis- 
sippi Bubble,"  raised  the  question  in  Scotland,  and  in  a  plan 
submitted  to  Parliament  for  supplying  the  deficiency  in  gold 
and  silver  money,  proposed  that  the  Government  appoint 
commissioners  to  appraise  lands  and  issue  notes  in  three 
modes :  first,  as  an  ordinary  loan  not  exceeding  two-thirds  of 
the  value  of  the  land  given  in  security :  second,  to  give  notes 
up  to  the  full  value  of  the  land,  and  to  enter  into  possession 
thereof  under  a  bond  to  redeed:  and  third,  to  buy  the  land 
and  give  notes  for  its  full  value. 

Law's  plan,  though  strongly  supported  by  the  court  party, 
was  finally  rejected.  Then  this  remarkable  man,  after  a 
checkered  career  as  a  duellist,  gambler  and  adventurer,  turned 
up  in  Paris  in  1715  with  about  a  half -million  dollars  of  mys- 
teriously gotten  gains,  revamped  his  Scotch  scheme,  gained 
the  ear  of  the  Duke  of  Orleans,  and  offered  to  found  a  bank 
of  issue  under  the  control  of  the  state,  with  notes  secured 
by  land  and  the  royal  revenues.  The  Government  declined 
at  first  to  identify  itself  with  the  project,  but  in  1716  granted 
him  a  charter  for  the  General  Bank  of  Law  and  Company 
(his  brother).  In  1718  the  Government  bought  the  majority 
of  the  stock  of  this  concern,  renamed  it  the  Eoyal  Bank,  with 
Law  as  president,  and  within  a  few  years  entrusted  it  or  its 
allies  vdth  the  receipt  of  the  taxes,  the  farming  of  the  reve- 
nues from  tobacco  and  other  sources,  and  the  management  of 
the  mint,  gave  it  a  trading  monopoly  in  the  South  Seas,  al- 
lowed it  to  absorb  the  Senegal  Company,  the  Company  of  the 


26  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

Indies,  the  Chiaa  and  India  Company,  and  also,  what  Law 
had  held  constantly  in  mind,  authorized  it  to  organize  the 
Company  of  the  West  to  which  was  granted  the  immense  prov- 
ince of  Louisiaaa  with  all  its  fabulous  stores  of  precious 
metals,  Elysian  fields  and  infinite  opportunities  for  making 
easy  fortunes.  But  the  downfall  of  this  greatest  of  plungers 
in  the  realm  of  finance  was  even  more  rapid  than  his  rise. 
In  1720  the  bubble  burst.  The  conduct  of  the  affairs  of  a 
nearly  bankrupt  nation  had  kept  him  too  busy  in  the  heyday 
of  his  power  to  develop  his  pet  land-credit  schemes,  and  the 
Budden  and  overwhelming  panic  destroyed  his  hopes  forever. 
His  desperate  attempt  to  shore  up  his  tottering  system  by 
ordering  the  Company  of  the  West  to  receive  the  bank's  notes 
at  par  in  stock  sales  disclosed  the  weakness  of  both  and 
brought  down  the  whole  in  ruin. 

The  next  stage  in  the  development  of  land  credit 
was  its  organization  in  Prussia  in  1769,  and  this  is  the 
most  important  of  all,  because  in  the  establishment  of 
the  Prussian  system  land  debentures  were  first  devised:  and 
yet  Frederick  the  Great,  in  the  edict  legalizing  their  use,  de- 
clared that  they  should,  "at  sales  of  estates,  payments  of 
loans,  etc.,  be  taken  and  circulated  as  coin  in  the  same  way 
as  the  parchment  mortgage  instruments  in  the  dukedoms  of 
Schweidnitz  and  Janer."  This  allusion  must  be  explained. 
In  Schweidnitz  and  Janer  real  property  could  not  be  encum- 
bered by  a  mere  contract  between  the  parties.  Judicial  pro- 
ceedings had  to  be  brought  and  the  consent  of  the  court 
obtained,  and  after  that  the  transaction  was  concluded,  not 
by  two  papers,  a  promissory  note  and  a  mortgage,  as  in  the 
IJnited  States,  but  by  one  ofBcial  document  signed  by  the 
parties,  the  judge  and  clerk,  and  duly  recorded.  Documents 
like  this  very  naturally  were  used  as  money  in  the  absence  of 
other  currency,  although  they  did  not  bear  the  fiat  of  the 
Government. 

Paper  money  based  solely  on  land  was  issued  during  the 
French  Eevolution.  In  1789  coin  had  vanished  from  France 
and  the  people  were  unable  to  pay  taxes.  The  bloody  and 
lawless  Government  was  in  dire  distress.    To  save  itself  from 


DEBENTUEES  27 

bankruptcy  it  confiscated  the  lands  of  the  Crown,  the  Church, 
and,  later  on,  of  fugitive  emigrants.  The  intention  was  to 
dispose  of  these  lands  for  public  purposes.  The  sales,  how- 
ever, were  too  slow  to  satisfy  fiscal  needs,  and  the  Government 
decided  to  issue  notes  in  the  nature  of  mortgage-bonds  against 
the  national  domains  as  a  substitute  for  metallic  currency. 
The  first  notes,  called  "assignats,"  bore  five  per  cent  interest, 
were  redeemable  within  five  years,  and  were  given  the  prefer- 
ence over  other  kinds  of  money  for  the  purchase  of  these 
lands.  It  was  presumed  that  a  holder  who  did  not  wish  to 
buy  lands  could  get  the  face  value  of  the  notes  from  some 
one  who  did  and  that  thus  the  whole  issue  would  be  gradually 
retired. 

In  1790  the  assignats  were  made  legal  tender  and  enor- 
mous quantities  of  them  were  put  in  circulation  without  just 
ratio  to  the  land.  The  land  was  repeatedly  reappraised  and 
overestimated.  Hence  the  assignats  underwent  rapid  depre- 
ciation. Perhaps  if  Mirabeau's  advice  had  been  followed  and 
the  issue  confined  to  one-haU  the  value  of  the  land,  they 
would  not  have  suffered  the  usual  fate  of  inconvertible  money. 
But  nine  billions  of  dollars  of  them  were  emitted,  and  even 
the  penalty  of  death  provided  for  all  creditors  who  refused 
to  take  them  could  not  for  long  stave  off  the  disastrous  end. 
In  1793  the  Government  ceased  to  issue  assignats  and  tried 
to  refund  them  by  a  new  form  of  currency  called  "mandats." 
The  difference  between  the  two  forms  was  that  the  mandats 
enabled  the  holder  to  take  immediate  possession  of  public 
lands,  whereas  the  assignats  could  be  offered  only  in  lieu  of 
cash  for  the  purchase  price.  But  this  expedient  did  very  little 
good,  and  the  Government  had  to  resort  at  last  to  repudia- 
tion, and  ia  1797  declared  aU  this  paper  money  outstanding 
to  be  null  and  void. 

America  also  established  bank  credits  upon  land  security. 
In  fact,  cooperative  land  credit  was  conceived  and  used  in 
New  England  39  years  before  it  appeared  in  Europe,  while 
the  land  banks  of  some  of  the  colonies  antedated  similar  insti- 
tutions in  continental  Europe  by  more  than  a  century  and 
actually  practiced  what  had  been  attempted  previously  in 


38  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

England  without  success.  As  early  as  1686  a  plan  for  a  bank 
to  issue  bills  and  give  credit  on  real  estate,  goods  and  mer- 
chandise was  approved  by  the  Governor  and  council  of  the 
province  of  Massachusetts  Bay,  with  the  recommendation 
that  such  biUs  "be  esteemed  as  current  money  in  all  receipts 
and  payments,"  even  for  His  Majesty's  revenues.  This  plan 
fell  through  in  1688,  but  the  contention  that  land  was  better 
than  specie  as  security  for  bills  was  persisted  in  and  spread 
far  and  wide. 

Pennsylvania  was  the  first  colony  to  take  a  definite  step. 
In  1722  trade  had  come  to  a  standstill  owing  to  the  lack  of 
an  adequate  medium  of  exchange.  Four  or  five  rich  importers 
had  bought  up  and  engrossed  the  staples  of  food  and  wear. 
They  sold  them  back  at  high  prices,  and  thus  got  hold  of  all 
the  hard  money,  which  they  loaned  out  at  eight  per  cent  and 
placed  most  of  the  tradespeople  in  their  debt.  Many  failures 
and  general  distress  resulted  from  this  oppression,  to  meet 
which  the  Government  founded  the  Public  Loan  OflSce  man- 
aged by  four  official  commissioners,  to  which  was  given  power 
to  emit  bills. 

These  bills  were  drawn  without  interest  in  small  denomi- 
nations, the  largest  being  $100,  and  they  were  issued  only  to 
borrowers,  who  had  to  give  a  promissory  note  with  bond  for 
judgment,  repayable  in  12  annual  payments  at  five  per  cent 
and  secured  by  mortgage  on  land  worth  double  the  amount  of 
the  loan.  No  borrower  could  obtain  less  than  $100  or  more 
than  $1,000  of  these  bills.  The  Office  was  inspected  by  a  com- 
mittee of  the  legislative  asseinbly,  and  accounts  were  settled 
every  six  months.  "It  is  inconceivable,"  says  history,  "what 
prodigious  good  effect  immediately  ensued  on  the  affairs  of 
the  province.  Commerce  revived  with  England,  Scotland  and 
Ireland.  The  poor  middling  people,  who  had  lands  or  houses 
to  pledge,  borrowed  from  the  Loan  Office,  and  paid  off  their 
usurious  creditors,  and  the  few  rich  men  had  to  build  ships 
and  launch  in  trade  again."  Having  accomplished  its  object 
and  broken  up  the  money  trust,  the  Office  went  out  of  busi- 
ness after  its  biUs  were  all  redeemed. 

In  1730  or  1732,  61  influential  landowners  of  the  colony 


DEBENTUEES  29 

of  Connectieut  obtained  from  the  assembly  a  charter  for  the 
New  London  Society  United  for  Trade  and  Commerce.  They 
paid  for  stock  subscribed  by  giving  their  promissory  notes 
due  in  13  years  at  five  per  cent  secured  by  mortgages  on  their 
lands.  The  Society  was  authorized  to  emit  bills  without 
interest  against  these  secured  notes,  which  it  agreed  to  accept 
as  money  in  all  payments  to  it.  In  other  words,  the  Society 
operated  solely  with  credit  capital  and  the  only  borrowers 
were  its  stockholders,  who  had  control  of  the  management. 
This  was  cooperative  land  credit  pure  and  simple,  and  gives 
to  Connecticut  the  honor,  which  is  usually  accorded  to  Ger- 
many, of  being  the  birthplace  thereof. 

The  biLLs  of  this  Connecticut  association  were  phrased  in 
the  form  of  the  public  paper  issued  by  the  colony.  They 
became  popular  immediately  and  were  freely  used  as  money 
by  the  people.  But  this  "swift  currency  of  the  New  London 
Society  bills  through  so  many  hands,"  as  Governor  Talcott 
records,  aroused  suspicion  as  to  the  object  of  this  novel  and 
unfamiliar  device.  The  next  year  he  caused  the  assembly 
to  decree  the  dissolution  of  the  Society  for  arrogating  govern- 
mental rights  and  to  order  the  bills  to  be  recalled.  The 
notes  and.  mortgages  were  then  assigned  ia  trust  to  the 
Governor  and  he  proceeded  to  wind  up  the  concern  whose 
affairs  contiuued  to  occupy  the  attention  of  the  assembly  imtil 
1749.  No  question  was  raised,  however,  as  to  the  soundness 
of  these  bUls. 

The  most  memorable  of  these  colonial  projects  for  utilizing 
land  as  security  for  public  or  private  bills  was  the  Land  Bank 
or  Manufactory  Scheme  launched  ia  Massachusetts  Bay 
Province  in  1740.  The  share  capital  of  this  association  was 
$750,000,  of  which  no  individual  member  was  allowed  to  hold 
less  than  $500  or  more  than  $10,000.  Subscriptions  were  not 
payable  immediately  in  cash.  Each  subscriber  agreed  to  pay 
five  on  the  hundred  of  the  principal  and  three  per  cent  use- 
money  annually  until  the  whole  amount  was  paid,  and  to 
give  a  mortgage  on  an  estate  in  land  to  secure  these  payments, 
which  could  be  made  in  produce  grown  or  manufactured  in 
the  province.    The  association  planned  to  issue  30-year  bills 


30  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

of  small  denominations  without  interest  up  to  the  full  amount 
of  this  share  capital.  These  were  redeemable  only  in  produce, 
but  the  association  and  the  subscribers,  so  long  as  they  held 
shares,  were  obligated  to  receive  them  for  all  payments  and 
in  trade  and  business  when  tendered  by  anybody.  AU  mem- 
bers were  jointly  and  severally  liable,  were  the  main  borrow- 
ers, and  had  votes  in  proportion  to  their  subscriptions;  hence 
in  its  general  outlines  the  association  was  similar  to  its  co- 
operative prototype  in  Connecticut. 

The  directors  of  this  extraordinary  financial  experiment 
were  among  the  most  prominent  citizens  of  Boston.  Judges 
and  legislators  were  connected  with  it.  Adroit  methods  of 
promotion  had  worked  the  people  up  to  such  a  point  of  fatu- 
ity that  the  majority  believed  that  the  means  had  finally 
been  found  for  creating  the  medium  of  exchange  so  much 
needed  for  relieving  the  misfortune  and  poverty  of  the  coun- 
try. Over  a  thousand  persons  subscribed  for  shares  and  a 
number  of  towns  agreed  to  accept  the  bills  of  the  Bank  for 
taxes. 

It  must  be  remembered  that  in  those  days  the  principles 
of  paper  tooney  were  not  clearly  understood.  The  sober- 
minded  citizens,  however,  realized  the  dangers  which  lurked 
in  the  Bank  and,  backed  by  the  provincial  governor,  they 
proceeded  to  suppress  it.  This  was  done  by  having  the  British 
Parliament  apply  to  the  American  colonies  the  Bubble  Act 
which  had  been  passed  in  1720  to  stop  the  craze  for  specula- 
tion fomented  in  England  by  John  Law's  mad  schemes. 
Armed  with  this  law,  promulgated  in  1741,  the  opponents 
of  the  Land  Bank  forced  it  into  liquidation.  Near-riots 
broke  out,  severe  measures  were  used,  and  almost  30  years 
elapsed  before  litigation  regarding  its  affairs  disappeared  from 
the  courts.  The  foreclosures,  attachments  and  arrests  made 
by  the  royal  Government  upon  the  property  and  persons  of 
the  numerous  members  of  this  unfortimate  concern  to  settle 
its  debts,  engendered,  according  to  Samuel  Adams,  as  much 
ill  will  as  the  Stamp  Act. 

The  historic  incidents  described  above  show  the  various 
ways  in  which  land  has  been  used  as  a  basis  for  money  and 


DEBENTUKES  31 

bank  credits,  public  or  private,  vagaries  of  the  old  dream  of 
mobilizing  the  soil.  As  a  basis  for  inconvertible  money,  land 
can  serve  no  purpose  whatever  except  as  a  measure  for  the  out- 
put, and  since  the  percentage  of  value  to  be  taken  for  the 
measure  may  be  adopted  or  changed  at  will,  the  security  of 
such  money  really  depends  upon  the  honesty  and  standing 
of  the  government  and  not  at  all  upon  the  land.  There  is  no 
denying,  however,  that  land  may  be  used  to  a  certain  extent 
for  convertible  money,  provided  the  government  is  the  owner. 
The  French  assignats  were  good  imtil  the  revolutionists  per- 
fidiously violated  their  faith.  Similar  instruments,  the  scrips 
formerly  issued  in  large  numbers  by  the  federal  and  state 
governments  in  the  United  States,  which  entitled  the  scripee 
or  his  assigns  to  allotments  in  the  public  domain,  were  always 
in  popular  demand.  In  fact,  as  the  available  area  for  home- 
steads decreased  the  value  of  these  certificates,  although  given 
as  bounty  or  for  insignificant  money  equivalent,  rose  to  near 
the  selling  price  of  land,  and  they  were  speedily  bought  up  by 
settlers  and  all  redeemed.  Divided  into  coupons  and  made 
legal  tender,  they  would  have  been  accepted  as  a  safe  and 
fluid  currency,  but  it  would  not  have  had  any  stability,  be- 
cause its  volume  would  have  been  subject  to  diminution  as  the 
land  was  sold  off. 

If  the  government  owned  no  land  and  should  issue  money 
against  mortgages  on  lands  of  others,  it  would  simply  be 
playing  the  role  of  a  lender,  with  all  the  attendant  costs  and 
risks  in  establishing  its  security.  It  would  have  to  lend  to 
all  landowners  equally  to  avoid  class  legislation  or  special 
privilege,  and  this  would  mean  that  individual  loans  would 
have  to  be  small  if  the  issue  were  to  be  kept  within  reason- 
able bounds.  Hence  the  government  would  find  this  Mnd  of 
money  exceedingly  expensive.  Moreover,  it  could  not  prose- 
cute defaults  to  foreclosure  and  eviction  in  the  event  of  panics, 
bad  crops  or  hard  times  without  being  held  up  to  public  exe- 
cration. As  a  consequence  this  money,  founded  on  something 
which  could  not  be  realized  upon  or  removed,  would  always 
remain  in  the  country  and  drive  out  the  good  money. 

These  objections,  which  bar  land  as  a  basis  for  money,  may 


32  RUKAL    CREDITS 

be  urged  also  against  its  nse  as  security  for  bills  of  banks, 
whether  controlled  by  private  parties  or  by  the  government. 
A  bank  with  one-fourth  of  its  capital  and  surplus  in  real- 
estate  mortgages  and  one-third  of  its  time  deposits  in  loans 
of  the  length  required  by  agricidture  would  be  likely  to  be  the 
first  to  go  to  the  wall  in  a  panic,  unless  its  borrowers  were 
mostly  depositors  and  stockholders  of  the  bank,  as  in  the 
case  of  a  cooperative  credit  society.  A  deposit  bank  which 
should  immobilize  its  assets  to  such  an  extent  would  in  fact 
completely  denature  itself  and  become  an  investment  com- 
pany. If  banks  must  depart  from  the  established  usages  of 
trade  and  commerce,  they  should  be  empowered  to  issue  deben- 
tures or  long-term  bonds  and  permitted  to  make  their  mort- 
gage loans  only  out  of  the  funds  raised  by  these  instruments. 
Deposits  are  entrusted  to  the  banks  upon  the  understandiag 
that  they  may  be  withdrawn  at  will  or  at  a  time  agreed  upon. 
The  custodians  should  not  be  allowed  to  abuse  this  trust  by 
sinking  them  in  loans  which  the  average  depositor  would  not 
care  personally  to  make.  Deposits  are  circulating  capital  and 
should  be  preserved  as  such. 

The  organization  of  land  credit  depends  upon  the  careful 
observance  of  this  distinction.  Landowners  cannot  be 
financed  by  deposits.  Their  needs  caU  for  investment  cap- 
ital, and  this  can  be  obtained  with  safety  and  profit  only  by 
institutions  authorized  to  issue  debentures.  The  form  and 
effect  of  the  debenture  in  Europe,  as  already  indicated,  are  an 
evolution  proceeding  from  the  unrealized  dream  of  mobilizing 
land  values  for  paper  money.  Tentative  projects  proved  the 
folly  of  this  hazy  dream,  and  led  Europe  to  reject  also  that 
other  mistaken  notion  that  land  may  be  used  as  a  security  for 
bank  credits.  Out  of  original  error  the  true  principles  sprang 
to  light  and  evolved  the  debenture,  which  has  come  as  near  to 
mobilizing  land  values  as  that  object  can  be  attained. 

The  only  characteristics  of  money  which  have  been  re- 
tained in  this  instrument  of  land  credit  are  that  it  may  be 
made  payable  to  bearer,  is  in  small  denominations,  without 
fixed  time  for  maturity,  and  is  exempted  from  taxes.  The 
circulation  of  the  debenture  has  been  facilitated  by  simplify- 


DEBENTUEES  33 

ing  the  formalities  for  transfer  and  by  making  it  a  legal  in- 
vestment for  almost  all  kinds  of  funds,  while  its  redemption 
has  been  assured  by  statutory  limitations  which  prevent  ex- 
cessive issue.  The  status  and  regulation  of  the  debenture, 
however,  vary  in  different  countries. 


CHAPTER  V 

THE    ORIGIN    OF    THE    GERMAN   LANDSCHAFTS 

German  Institutions  for  Credit. — ^Number  and  Location  of  Land- 
schafts. — Definition  of  Landschaft. — Landsehafts  Now  Voluntary 
But  First  Compulsory. — Origin  in  Prussia  After  Seven  Tears' 
War. — Biiring's  Plan. — ^Arguments  for  the  Scheme. — ^Adoption 
and  Success. 

The  German  Empire  comprises  four  kingdoms,  §ix  grand 
duchies,  five  duchies,  seven  principalities,  three  free  towns, 
and  one  territory.  The  division  of  government  between  the 
Empire  and  its  constituent  parts  is  somewhat  like  that  be- 
tween the  nation  and  states  in  the  United  States.  Besides  the 
imperial  legislation  on  the  subject,  many  special  and  general 
laws  relating  to  real-estate  credit  are  in  force  in  these  26 
states.  As  a  consequence  there  is  a  great  variety  of  German 
institutions  especially  organized  for  according  such  credit, 
many  of  which  were  chartered  long  ago,  in  the  days  of  inde- 
pendent sovereignties.  These  institutions  may  be  classified 
generally  as  landsehafts,  public  land-credit  banks,  land-im- 
provement associations,  governmental  institutions  for  assist- 
ing small  holders  to  acquire  homesteads,  and  joint-stock  mort- 
gage companies. 

The  landschaft  is  the  origiual  type  of  the  land-credit  in- 
stitution, and  it  is  considered  the  best  because  it  can  lend 
money  at  the  lowest  interest  rates,  be  most  lenient  to  debtors 
in  defaxJt,  and  issue  the  safest  securities  for  investors.  There 
are  23  institutions  of  this  kind.  Of  the  larger  German  states, 
only  Baden,  Hesse,  Oldenburg  and  Alsace-Lorraine  are 
witiiout  any.  Eighteen  are  in  Prussia  and  cover  all  that 
kingdom  except  the  Ehine  Province,  Hesse-Nassau,  the  Mu- 
nicipal District  of  Berlin,  and  an  enclave  in  Wiirttemberg 

34 


ORIGIN  OF  THE  GERMAN  LANDSCHAFTS      35 

known  as  Hohenzollern  Land;  eight  of  the  Prussian  land- 
schafts  have  combiaed  to  form  the  Central  Landschaft. 
Saxony  has  two  landschafts,  and  Bavaria,  Wiirttemberg, 
Mecklenburg-Schwerin,  and  Brunswick  each  have  one.  In 
Wiirttemberg  the  landschaft  accepts  mortgages  on  both  rural 
and  urban  properties,  but  the  landschafts  ia  the  other  states 
lend  only  on  lands  outside  of  the  cities. 

Each  landschaft  was  created  by  a  special  provincial  act 
which  gave  it  the  right  in  perpetuity  to  operate  vrithia  its 
prescribed  area  and  vested  it  with  such  official  powers  as  to 
make  it  a  branch  of  the  government.  There  is  no  general 
law  relating  to  landschafts  except  the  Prussian  law  of  1897 
which  extended  the  landschaft  privileges  to  all  which  should 
be  founded  before  1900.  No  persons  took  advantage  of  this 
law  nor  has  any  landschaft  been  organized  in  recent  time  for 
farmers  outside  of  Bavaria,  so  it  may  be  assumed  that  there 
is  no  need  or  inducement  for  an  increase  in  their  number. 
Those  which  date  back  to  the  eighteenth  century  are  known 
as  the  old  landschafts,  the  others  as  the  new  landschafts; 
and  one  consisting  entirely  of  noble  estates  is  called  a  "ritter- 
schaft." 

4  landschaft  is  an  association  of  landowners,  supervised 
and  controlled  by  the  government,  and  empowered  to  issue 
debentures  on  the  joint  and  several  liability  of  the  mem- 
bers and  to  give  them  to  members  only,  in  exchange,  how- 
ever, for  their  several  obligations,  secured  by  mortgages,  to 
make  stipulated  payments  into  its  treasury  at  stated  inter- 
vals; it  is  further  empowered  to  receive,  invest  and  finally 
apply  these  payments  for  the  redemption  'of  the  debentures 
as  they  mature.  Several  concerns  with  shares,  chartered  under 
the  cooperative  law,  are  sometimes  ranked  with  the  land- 
schafts, but  the  real  landschafts  have  no  capital  stock,  nor 
do  they  possess  any  cooperative  feature  except  the  mutual 
liability  of  members  and  the  meager  right  allowed  to  them  to 
vote  for  lists  of  officers  to  be  presented  to  the  Crown  for 
approval. 

Although  the  first  of  the  landschafts  was  founded  in 
1769,  the  existence  of  these  institutions  was  scarcely  known 


36  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

outside  of  Prussia  as  late  as  1845.  Charles  Edward  Eoyer, 
Commissioner  of  the  French  Ministry  of  Agriculture,  in 
a  report  rendered  in  the  latter  year  said:  "It  would  be  dif- 
ficult for  me  to  express  the  astonishment  which  I  felt  at 
Stettiu  and  Breslau,  where  the  landschaft  had  existed  for 
more  than  three-quarters  of  a  century  and  placed  in  circula- 
tion over  30  millions  of  dollars  of  debentures,  upon  learning 
that  public  officials  and  wealthy  citizens  were  unable  to  give 
me  any  information  about  the  association,  which  they  hardly 
knew  by  name.  The  bankers  especially  spoke  lightly  of  the 
association,  and  this  struck  me  as  strange  at  first,  although  it 
was  entirely  natural  among  men  accustomed  as  they  to  con- 
sider the  importance  of  financial  operations  by  the  rapidity 
of  the  flow  of  money  and  the  big  profits  resultiug  therefrom 
for  them." 

The  landschafts  are  still  little  considered  in  the  finan- 
cial world,  since  they  have  small  paid  staffs  of  employees, 
avoid  all  speculative  ventures,  and  make  no  effort  whatever 
to  increase  their  business,  while  their  debentures  circulate 
only  within  their  respective  provinces  and  represent  mainly 
the  loans  which  early  members  obtained  with  the  intention  of 
leaving  them  as  a  permanent  burden  upon  their  estates. 

All  the  new  landschafts  are  voluntary  associations,  but 
the  oldest  was  compulsory,  the  nobility  within  its  jurisdic- 
tion having  been  obliged  by  royal  decree  to  become  members. 
This  arbitrary  proceeding  was  taken  as  a  measure  of  public 
necessity,  to  bring  financial  relief  to  sufferers  from  the  devas- 
tation of  the  Seven  Years'  War,  and  it  saved  400  of  the  best 
families  of  Silesia  from  ruin,  as  related  by  Frederick  the 
Great  in  one  of  his  letters.  The  victories  of  this  conqueror 
had  been  dearly  bought.  He  made  of  Prussia  a  mighty 
nation,  but  burdensome  taxes  and  the  ravages  of  contending 
armies  had  brought  trade  and  commerce  to  a  standstill  and 
pressed  with  particular  severity  upon  agriculture  and  land- 
owners. A  fragment  of  a  manuscript  of  Professor  Dieterici, 
then  director  of  the  statistical  bureau  of  the  Ministry  of 
Agriculture  at  Berlin,  portrays  the  damage  done  to  private 
property  by  this  war,  and  says  that  de  Struensee,  the  Prime 


ORIGIN  OF  THE  GEEMAK  LANDSCHAFTS      37 

Minister,  attributed  the  land-credit  troubles  after  the  peace 
of  1763  to  the  following  causes : 

Many  states  had  been  entirely  ruined,  notably  those  in 
■which  the  armies  had  been  encamped  for  a  long  time.  The  soil 
remained,  it  is  true,  but  aU  which  was  necessary  for  giving  it 
value  had  disappeared.  Buildings  were  burned.  The  scattered 
livestock  had  died  of  hunger.  Farm  implements  were  rusted 
and  rotten,  and  the  fields  lay  im.cultivated.  The  value  of  the 
land  had  diminished  50  or  60  per  cent,  and  where  the  owner 
owed  a  big  part  of  the  price  at  which  he  purchased  it  before 
the  war,  he  was  utterly  unable  to  pay  the  interest  on  his  debt, 
to  say  nothing  of  the  principal  at  maturity.  Niunerous  de- 
faults were  made,  and  the  resulting  foreclosures  reduced  land 
values  stiU  further  and  excited  distrust  in  the  money  lenders  as 
to  the  worth  of  the  security,  who  thereupon  demanded  repay- 
ment of  all  sums  advanced  and  brought  about  a  crisis. 

During  the  war  landowners  had  obtained  high  prices  for 
farm  produce,  a.nd  had  paid  in  Saxon  tiers  not  only  taxes  but 
even  interest  dues  in  this  inferior  money.  This  sufficed  for  a 
while  as  a  compensation  for  the  cattle  and  supplies  which  the 
armies  had  foraged  off  their  lands.  But  after  the  peace  every- 
thing suddenly  changed.  The  price  of  produce  fell.  Taxes  and 
interest  were  required  to  be  paid  in  specie  of  the  standard  of 
1784,  and  the  cost  of  labor  continued  to  rise.  Moreover  the 
landowners,  who  had  been  tempted  into  extravagance  by  the 
high  prices  they  received  during  the  war,  were  unable  to  change 
their  habits,  and  their  ruin  became  inevitable. 

The  first  remedy  which  Frederick  the  Great  employed 
with  the  hope  of  relieving  the  indebted  landowners  was  to 
ignore  the  rights  of  the  creditors  and  stay  by  royal  decree 
the  payment  of  interest  for  three  years.  The  stay  law,  sub- 
sequently extended  for  another  period,  utterly  destroyed  the 
credit  of  all  who  resorted  to  it  and  left  them  at  the  mercy 
of  usurers.  The  few  loans  which  were  granted  drew  10 
per  cent  interest  with  two  or  three  per  cent  of  commissions. 
Dr.  Fassenbender  adds  that  lenders  also,  having  reserved  the 
right  to  demand  payment  on  a  few  months'  notice,  availed 
themselves  of  this  privilege  for  exacting  new  commissions 
repeatedly. 


38  EUEAL   CEBDITS 

Finding  that  his  remedy  only  intensified  the  miseries  and 
dangers  of  the  situation,  Frederick  the  Great  decided  to  recon- 
sider a  plan  submitted  to  him  by  an  obscure  merchant  named 
Biiriag,  who  evidently  had  studied  John  Law's  old  schemes. 
This  plan  was  based  on  the  idea  of  creating  a  public  inter- 
mediary between  lenders  and  borrowers,  and  using  the  com- 
bined estates  of  landowners  as  a  collective  security  for  de- 
bentures.   A  translation  follows : 

The  true  capital  of  a  country  consists  in  cash  and  land. 
The  value  of  the  latter  is  ten  times  greater  than  the  former, 
and  if  only  a  small  portion  of  it  were  mobilized,  it  would  abim- 
dantly  suffice  for  the  credit  needs  of  the  kingdom.  This  could 
be  accomplished  by  establishing  a  land  union  bank  (land- 
schaftscasse)  with  power  to  make  a  valuation  of  all  the  estates 
of  the  nobles  when  requested  and  to  lend  them  one-half  or  two- 
thirds  thereof  on  mortgage  so  that  they  may  pay  oS  pressing 
creditors.    The  loans  should  be  made  in  the  following  manner: 

First,  provincial  mortgage-bonds  or  debentures  shall  be  is- 
sued in  denominations  of  $360  and  $720  payable  to  bearer  with 
four  per  cent  interest,  guaranteed  by  the  land-credit  bank  and 
secured  by  the  estates  mortgaged  to  it.  The  bank  shall  give 
debentures  to  each  landowner  up  to  one-half  or  two-thirds  of 
his  estate  as  may  be  determined  by  the  management. 

Second,  landowners  shall  pay  four  and  a  half  or  five  per  cent 
semi-annually  to  the  bank  on  their  loans,  but  the  bank  shall 
pay  only  four  per  cent  once  a  year  to  the  holders  of  the  deben- 
tures. 

Third,  the  difference  of  one-half  or  one  per  cent  shall  be  left 
at  the  disposal  of  the  bank  for  meeting  expenses  and  salaries. 
Any  remainder,  together  with  the  income  from  the  use  of  the 
semi-annual  payments,  shall  be  set  aside  as  a  separate  provision 
against  accidents,  such  as  death  of  livestock  and  damages  by 
hail,  fire,  droughts,  or  war,  because  in  these  cases  the  nobility 
might  not  be  able  to  make  their  interest  pajrments  out  of  their 
damaged  estates.  In  such  an  event  the  estate  should  be  re- 
valued and  the  damage  made  good  out  of  this  fund. 

Advances  may  be  made  up  to  only  one-half  or  two-thirds  of 
the  estimated  damages,  according  to  the  plan  used  for  the  origi- 
nal loan.  Eules  for  estimating  damages  shall  be  fixed  by  the 
Eing's  Cabinet.    Since  Your  Majesty  has  graciously  promised 


OEIGIN  OF  THE  GEEMAN  LANDSCHAFTS      39 

a  capital  for  tliis  enterprise,  the  interest  thereon  might  be  used 
for  this  fund. 

If  anyone  fail  to  make  his  semi-annual  payments  promptly, 
his  estate  should  be  offered  for  sale  at  once.  I  do  not  favor 
receiverships,  for  they  are  an  eternal  curse. 

Fourth,  matters  relating  to  the  estates  of  crown  tenants 
shall  be  decided  by  three  nearest  borrowers  of  the  same  class, 
or  better  still  a  special  arrangement  for  loans  should  be  pro- 
vided for  them. 

Fifth,  care  should  be  taken  that  no  defaults  occur,  and  that 
the  principal  and  interest  of  the  debentures  be  never  altered. 

Sixth,  inasmuch  as  this  great  and  important  work  would 
require  some  cash  to  begin  with,  it  might  be  well  for  your 
Majesty  to  set  aside  a  fund  for  this  purpose.  Otherwise  the 
Banco  [a  commercial  bank  then  in  existence]  might  get  enough 
money  at  three  per  cent  to  buy  up  these  four  per  cent  debentures 
and  draw  the  interest  out  of  the  country  and  ruin  it.  Further- 
more, the  Banco  should  be  required  to  sell  debentures  with 
accrued  interest  immediately  upon  their  coming  into  its  hands. 

Seventh,  there  is  no  need  to  have  the  name  of  the  debtor  or 
a  description  of  his  estate  appear  in  the  debentures.  They 
should  be  made  payable  to  bearer.  Thus  they  would  have  easy 
negotiability  and  also  be  as  good  currency  as  banknotes,  for 
there  is  no  reason  to  suppose  that  many  of  them  would  ever  be 
returned  for  redemption.  In  a  short  time  they  might  be  quoted 
at  a  premium. 

This  great  project  could  be  started  at  once  without  many 
conferences  or  discussions,  because  it  would  be  voluntary  for 
everyone  to  avail  himself  of  its  assistance.  No  guaranty  of  the 
province  will  be  required.  The  guaranty  of  the  bank  and  the 
mortgaged  estates  would  be  sufficient,  if  legal  remedies  were 
provided  to  assure  prompt  recovery. 

Eighth,  severe  penalties  should  be  imposed  on  any  person 
who  should  take  any  of  these  debentures  out  of  the  country. 
No  stranger  should  be  permitted  to  purchase  them  either  di- 
rectly or  through  agents  residing  here,  and  thus  draw  the  inter- 
est out  of  the  country.  In  case  of  a  violation  of  the  law  the 
entire  principal  should  be  forfeited,  one  half  going  to  the  in- 
former and  the  other  half  to  the  bank. 

If  -a,  stranger  should  consimae  the  interest  here,  no  mon^ 
would  leave  the  country  and  the  matter  would  adjust  itself. 
This  would  be  better  than  borrowing  the  capital  abroad  at  the 


40  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

lowest  rates,  for  in  this  latter  event,  the  entire  amount  bor- 
rowed would  go  out  in  the  way  of  interest,  and  the  coimtiy 
would  stiU  have  to  pay  the  principal. 

In  Holland,  for  instance,  the  provincial  bonds  yield  only  two 
and  one-haM  per  cent  and  are  not  payable  to  bearer  as  these 
debentures  would  be.  How  much  more  valuable  these  deben- 
tures would  be  with  their  four  per  cent  interest  and  easy  nego- 
tiability which  would  enable  them  to  be  exchanged  for  cash 
any  day!  Would  not  the  Hollanders  absorb  this  paper  with- 
out our  noticing  it  and  finally  ruin  us  unless  precaution  be 
taken? 

Ninth,  the  business  and  privilege  of  the  post  office  in  trans- 
ferring money  from  place  to  place  would  perhaps  be  seriously 
interfered  with  if  debentures  equal  to  the  amoxmt  of  the  landed 
debt  and  accrued  interest  be  issued  and  become  current  as  cash 
in  trade.  So  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  tax  should  be  charged 
upon  transfers  of  these  debentures. 

If  it  should  ever  become  necessary  to  withdraw  these  deben- 
tures from  circulation,  the  retirement  could  be  accomplished 
easily  and  gradually  by  forbidding  other  lenders  to  charge  more 
than  four  per  cent  interest  on  mortgage. 

The  interest  rate  on  money  would  naturally  fall  as  soon 
as  an  abundance  of  currency  had  been  obtained  through  the 
issue  of  these  debentures.  The  landowners  would  then  be  able 
to  obtain  new  loans  at  four  per  cent  or  less.  They  need  not 
wait  for  action  by  the  bank.  They  could  take  the  debentures 
over  to  the  bank,  which  would  at  once  cancel  their  mortgages. 
Thus  the  debentures  would  disappear  from  circulation  owing 
to  the  fact  that  the  interest  rates  of  the  bank  were  one-half  of 
one  per  cent  or  one  per  cent  more  than  those  of  other  lenders. 

Methods  should  be  devised  for  retiring  these  debentures  as 
well  as  arranging  for  a  plenty  of  them,  according  to  the  safe 
rule  which  must  be  followed  invariably  in  matters  concerning 
the  state.  Otherwise  they  would  lose  value  as  currency;  and 
when  the  end  had  come,  as  the  proverb  says,  "the  purse  is 
worth  as  much  as  the  money."  It  wouJd  not  be  difi5cxdt  at  all 
to  cause  property  to  rise  over  50  per  cent  in  value  by  increasing 
the  volume  of  currency;  but  the  state  must  observe  correct 
financial  principles,  and  see  that  money,  real  estate  and  goods 
be  kept  at  fair  proportions,  else  the  best  arrangement  would  fall 
to  pieces  and  one  thing  after  another  be  ruined. 

The  objection  may  be  raised.  How  is  this  plan  to  help  those 


OEIGIJSr  OF  THE  GEEMAN  LANDSCHAFTS     41 

landowners  -who  already  owe  debts  exceeding  three-fourths  or 
more  of  the  value  of  their  estates?  The  answer  is  that  what 
has  been  said  above  clearly  shows:  (o)  that  even  they  would 
profit  from  this  plan  because,  the  supply  of  money  being 
increased,  they  would  not  be  pressed  so  much  by  their  creditors ; 
and  (h)  even  if  their  properties  should  be  put  up  at  forced 
sale,  they  would  be  sold  at  20  to  30  per  cent  over  the  present 
price,  because  every  purchaser  would  know  that  he  could  im- 
mediately get  back  an  amount  of  cash  equal  to  one-half  or  two- 
thirds  of  their  appraised  value. 

At  present,  however,  properties  are  often  sold  at  less  than 
their  appraised  value,  and  hardly  one-half  of  the  mortgage 
creditors  recover  all  their  loans.  Although  there  perhaps  would 
be  no  surplus  at  the  sales  under  this  plan,  yet  this  ruinous  loss 
could  never  occur.  There  is  no  way  to  help  a  debtor  who  falls 
in  debt  over  and  over  again,  except  by  making  him  a  present 
of  money. 

The  majority  of  the  nobles  may  now  be  regarded  as  ruined, 
in  view  of  the  present  condition  of  their  estates.  The  number 
of  livestock  is  insufficient,  causing  a  lack  of  manure  and  conse- 
quently poorer  crops.  How  are  they  to  pay  their  interest? 
Their  estates  are  deteriorating  daily  and  decreasing  in  value. 
If  you  go  back  to  the  serfs  who  depend  on  their  helpless  land- 
lords in  case  of  crop  failures  or  death  of  cattle,  where  will  you 
find  the  dues  which  must  be  rendered  to  the  king?  The  loss 
suffered  by  landlord  and  tenant  on  account  of  the  deteriorated 
fields  falls  likewise  upon  the  king  and  the  entire  country. 

It  would  also  be  desirable  for  Tour  Majesty  to  allow  the 
benefits  of  this  plan  to  be  extended  to  the  owners  of  lands  im- 
proved by  buildings  in  the  principal  cities  of  the  kingdom. 
This  could  be  easily  arranged,  and  would  stop  hundreds  of  law- 
suits and  save  great  numbers  of  persons  from  the  misfortune 
of  losing  all  that  they  possess. 

Properly  arranged  and  carefully  managed,  this  plan  might 
be  of  great  advantage  for  the  entire  country,  and  give  the  state 
an  inner  strength  surpassing  aU  expectations. 

The  arguments  advanced  by  Biiring  in  support  of  his 
plan  are  well  understood  in  these  days,  but  they  were  new 
to  his  time.  He  called  attention  to  the  fact  that  money 
lenders  would  not  make  loans  unless  they  were  able  to  ex- 


42  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

amine  the  property  and  investigate  the  character  of  the 
owner;  and  that  inasmuch  as  they  were  likely  to  make  mis- 
takes in  judging  values  and  the  capacity  for  repayment,  they 
invariably  compensated  themselves  for  the  risk  incurred  by 
chargiug  the  borrower  with  an  insurance  premium  in  the 
form  of  high  interest  rates.  Money  lenders,  moreover,  al- 
though satisfied  with  the  soundness  of  mortgages,  were  often 
deterred  from  making  such  investments  on  account  of  the 
immobilization  of  their  capital  resulting  therefrom. 

In  Prussia,  it  was  true,  lenders  had  the  right  of  exact- 
ing repayment  upon  a  few  months'  notice,  but  even  this 
short  delay  frequently  deprived  them  of  a  chance  for  some 
good  bargain.  Besides  they  were  never  sure  that  the  bor- 
rower would  be  able  to  repay  at  maturity,  and  they  dreaded 
the  heavy  expenses  of  foreclosure  in  the  event  of  a  default. 
The  lenders  of  course  might  sell  their  claims  instead  of  call- 
ing them  in.  This,  however,  was  an  empty  right,  because 
purchasers  could  not  be  found  at  will.  But  an  establish- 
ment which  occupies  itself  habitually  in  seeking  and  accept- 
ing disposable  capital,  in  Biiriug's  opinion,  would  not  encoun- 
ter these  difficulties,  since  it  would  be  in  a  far  better  posi- 
tion to  attract  money  lenders  than  an  isolated  landowner  who 
does  not  maintain  constant  relations  with  the  investing  public 
So  he  proposed  the  foundation  of  a  great  central  land-credit 
bank  with  powers  to  issue  debentures  against  mortgages  on 
the  estates  of  all  persons  in  the  kingdom,  and  he  thought 
that  these  would  circulate  as  ready  money  by  reason  of 
their  soundness  and  popularity,  if  official  supervision  were 
provided. 

Biiring's  plan  led  directly  to  the  organization  of  the  land- 
sehafts,  but  it  was  materially  changed  before  being  adopted. 
Frederick  the  Great  discarded  the  idea  of  a  central  institu- 
tion for  that  of  a  separate  landschaft  for  each  province,  ex- 
cluded urban  and  plebeian  properties  as  securities,  and  con- 
fined the  benefits  entirely  to  the  rural  estates  of  the  nobility. 
He  also  required  the  names  and  estates  of  the  borrowers 
to  be  mentioned  in  the  debentures,  but  in  other  respects  he 
went  the  full  length  of  Biiring's  suggestions  in  trying  to 


OEIGIN  OP  THE  GEEMAN  LANDSCHAFTS      43 

make  these  instruments  of  land  credit  pass  current  as  paper 
money. 

The  first  landsehaft  was  the  one  created  for  Silesia  by  a 
cabiaet  order  signed  by  Frederick  the  Great  on  August  29, 
1769.  The  order  blanketed  aU  the  rural  lands  of  the  nobility 
in  that  province  with  a  perpetual  lien  in  favor  of  the  asso- 
ciation as  a  secvirity  for  any  debentures  it  might  issue,  de- 
creed these  noble  farmers  to  be  members  thereof,  and  enjoined 
them  to  assemble  and  complete  its  organization.  This  was 
done  on  July  15,  1770,  and  the  King  granted  the  landsehaft 
$216,000,  later  increased  to  $432,000,  and  also  subjected  the 
crown  lands  to  this  collective  liability. 

The  association  appraised  all  the  lands  within  its  juris- 
diction, took  mortgages  from  the  members  who  wished  credit 
and  gave  them  debentures  in  exchange.  But  it  had  no  arrange- 
ment for  amortization.  It  did  not  even  collect  the  interest 
on  the  mortgages.  Payments  were  made  directly  by  the 
borrowers  to  the  lenders  as  before.  The  holders  did  not 
have  any  recourse  against  the  association  in  the  event  of 
default  in  payments  on  the  debentures  until  they  had  ex- 
hausted their  legal  remedies  against  the  persons  and  estates 
named  therein.  Then  if  the  association  were  called  upon, 
it  could  bring  its  special  summary  proceedings  against  the 
delinquent,  and  if  the  judgment  were  not  satisfied  by  him  it 
could  levy  assessments  on  the  other  members  for  the  de- 
ficiency. 

It  wiU  be  seen  that  the  landsehaft  as  first  devised  was 
not  intended  to  alter  the  direct  relation  between  the  borrower 
and  the  lender.  It  acted  simply  as  an  impartial  intermediary 
between  them  without  any  responsibility  or  duty  on  its  part 
except  to  see  that  the  mortgages  and  debentures  were  properly 
executed  and  to  enforce  the  collective  liability  of  the  mem- 
bers on  the  defaults.  Being  founded  and  financed  by  the 
government  and  connected  with  it,  the  association  was  in 
truth  its  official  organ  for  refunding  the  enormous  mass  of 
debts  which  encumbered  the  land  as  a  result  of  the  war  and 
public  disorders  and  converting  them  into  obligations  with 
reasonable  terms.    It  accomplished  this  purpose  so  well  that 


44  EUEAL   CREDITS 

the  interest  rate  was  immediately  reduced  to  five  per  cent  and 
soon  afterwards  to  four  per  cent,  and  this  success  induced 
the  nobles  in  five  other  Prussian  provinces  to  form  associa- 
tions along  the  same  lines. 

Nevertheless  these  old  associations  imderwent  changes  in 
the  course  of  time.  The  objects  and  methods  which  they  and 
the  new  associations  subsequently  formed  now  pursue  differ 
considerably  from  those  of  the  early  days.  Some  of  the  first 
debentures  are  still  in  circulation  but  debentures  of  similar 
form  are  issued  no  more.  Originally  the  word  "landschaft" 
signified  a  stretch  of  land  with  boimdaries  politically  or  other- 
wise defined,  and  only  by  derivation  has  it  come  to  mean 
the  institution  operating  thereupon. 


CHAPTER  VI 

THE    SILESIAN  LAKDSCHAFT:    ITS    STETJCTUEE 

Organization. — Executive  Coimeil. — ^District  BoaTds. — Standing  Com- 
mittees.— General  Assembly. — ^Permanent  Committee. — Circles. — 
Bank  of  the  SUesian  Landschaft. — ^Bureaus  of  Loans  to  Non- 
members. 

Although  called  an  association,  the  landschaft  of  Silesia 
is  in  fact  a  great  public  land-credit  system  covering  the  entire 
province,  which  is  divided  for  this  purpose  into  nine  dis- 
tricts, each  subdivided  into  two  or  more  circles.  Each  district 
has  an  association  of  its  own  and  all  the  associations  are 
united  imder  one  general  management;  hence  the  organi- 
zation is  decentralized.  Supervision  is  exercised  by  the  Min- 
ister of  Agriculture  through  a  royal  commissioner.  The 
headquarters  of  the  landschaft  is  in  the  capital  city  of  Breslau, 
where  it  ovms  and  operates  a  large  banking  corporation. 
Branches  of  this  bank  have  been  opened  in  seven  of  the 
nine  districts  and  it  does  busiaess  with  all  comers.  The 
districts  maintain  bureaus  for  extending  credit  on  agricul- 
tural lands  of  non-members  within  their  borders. 

Silesia  is  about  one-third  the  size  of  Ohio,  but  has  nearly 
one  million  more  inhabitants.  Its  area  is  15,569  square 
miles  and  in  1910  it  had  a  population  of  5,225,963.  The 
landschaft  system  included  originally  only  the  farm  and 
forest  lands  which  belonged  in  1770  to  the  nobility  and  the 
Crown.  These,  whether  mortgaged  or  not,  are  charged  per- 
petually by  Frederick  the  Great's  order  with  a  coDeetive 
liability  for  the  debentures.  The  lands  of  the  Church  were 
brought  within  its  scope  a  few  years  later.  In  1807  an  edict 
of  the  Prussian  King  permitting  plebeians  to  acquire  estates 
of  nobles  practically  eliminated  the  requisite  of  rank.     In 

45 


4:6  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

1815  another  royal  edict  decreed  municipalities  to  be  eligible 
to  membership  upon  contributing  certain  sums  to  the  reserves 
of  the  landsehaf t.  Hence  the  system  now  embraces  all  rural 
Silesia,  with  the  forests,  mines  and  fisheries  therein.  The 
land  of  a  member  must  be  worth  at  least  $7,500,  else  he 
cannot  become  an  official  or  a  borrower.  Credit,  however,  may 
be  accorded  by  the  district  bureaus  to  a  non-member  on  a 
plot  yielding  a  revenue  of  only  $24  a  year.  The  bank  dis- 
counts notes  given  by  resident  borrowing  farmers  for  sums 
as  small  as  $73. 

Eegisters  are  kept  at  headquarters  and  in  all  the  districts 
for  recording  the  title,  description,  alterations  and  transfers 
of  a  member's  property,  together  with  the  debentures  issued 
against  it  and  the  mortgage,  given  to  secure  them.  These 
registers  are  legal  and  indisputable  proof  of  their  contents. 
If  the  value  of  an  estate  fall  below  the  minimum,  the  owner 
is  notified  in  writing,  and  if  he  offers  no'  valid  defense,  he 
forfeits  his  membership,  this  fact  is  noted  in  the'  registers,  and 
his  loan  is  recalled.  An  owner  is  admitted  to  membership 
and  his  lands  to  registration  by  resolution  of  the  permanent 
committee  preceded  by  a  vote  of  the  board  of  the  district  in 
which  the  land  is  situated.  The  only  reason  which  a  person 
now  has  for  joining  is,  of  course,  to  obtain  a  loan,  and  he 
ceases  to  be  a  member  after  this  has  beeji  paid. 

All  officers  are  selected  from  among  members  who  are 
borrowers  up  to  specified  amounts,  who  possess  irreproach- 
able characters  and  known  business  abilities.  They  must 
resign  if  their  estates  are  sold  in  foreclosure  or  sequestered 
for  defaults.  No  one  holding  an  office  of  profit  or  trust  under 
the  government  can  be  an  official  of  the  landschaft  unless 
by  consent  of  his  superiors  and  of  the  executive  council  of 
the  landschaft.  This  rule  was  adopted  to  bar  politics.  Nor 
can  anyone,  clerk  or  official,  hold  two  offices  at  the  same 
time,  or  be  connected  with  any  other  land-mortgage  institu- 
tion. The  term  of  an  elective  office  is  six  years.  Officials  are 
bonded  and  sworn  and  enjoined  to  observe  absolute  secrecy 
respecting  the  affairs  of  the  association.  They  are  responsible 
in  personal  damages  for  the  strict  performance  of  their 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAPT:  ITS   STEUCTUEE      47 

duties,  and  have  rank,  power  and  obligations  as  public  officers. 
They  are  bound  to  serve  if  elected  and  cannot  resign  without 
reasonable  excuse.  Acceptance  of  reelection  is  optional.  Pen- 
sions are  provided  upon  superannuation  and  for  poor  widows 
and  orphans  of  deceased  officials. 

The  Silesian  landschaft  is  administered  by  an  executive 
council,  district  boards,  district  standing  committees,  and 
circle  meetings.  Over  these  bodies  are  the  permanent  com- 
mittee and  the  general  assembly. 

I.  The  executive  council  is  composed  of  the  president, 
three  vice-presidents  and  two  counselors.  It  is  the  managing 
head  of  the  system,  represents  it  against  the  outside  world, 
and  carries  on  the  business  in  its  own  name. 

The  president  is  appointed  by  the  King  of  Prussia  from 
three  candidates  elected  by  the  members.  He  must  be  a 
Silesian  of  noble  birth.  He  receives  no  salary.  He  must 
have  held  office  formerly  in  the  landschaft.  He  is  head  of 
the  executive  council  and  presides,  if  he  wishes,  at  the  meet- 
ings of  the  permanent  and  any  other  committee.  He  may 
exercise  disciplinary  powers  of  warning  and  fining  over  the 
executive  council  and  may  appoint  an  examiner  to  investigate 
the  acts  of  its  members  or  of  any  other  official,  but  he  can- 
not dismiss  a  member  of  the  executive  council  without  the 
approval  of  the  King.  Once  every  four  years,  with  one  of  the 
coimselors,  he  must  make  a  personal  inspection  of  each  dis- 
trict. His  alternate  in  the  council  is  the  ranking  vice-presi- 
dent. A  special  commissioner,  appointed  by  the  King  for  the 
period  of  the  session,  may  take  the  place  of  the  president  in 
the  permanent  committee  and  general  assembly. 

The  three  vice-presidents  are  elected  from  upper,  middle 
and  lower  Silesia  by  the  members  living  in  these  divisions, 
subject  to  the  approval  of  the  King.  Only  those  members  are 
eligible  who  have  finished  a  course  in  the  university  and  have 
acquired  an  exact  knowledge  of  the  part  of  the  country 
they  represent.  They  receive  no  salary  but,  in  common  with 
the  president,  are  allowed  traveling  expenses  and  the  per  diem 
given  to  members  of  the  permanent  committee. 

The  two  counselors  are  appointed  by  the  executive  council 


48  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

but  in  order  to  avoid  an  objectionable  selection,  a  report  on 
the  candidates  for  the  office  is  obtained  from  every  district. 
They  must  be  graduates  in  law  and  have  passed  the  examina- 
tions qualifying  them  to  be  judges.  They  are  employed  as 
salaried  and  permanent  officials.  The  counselors  are  author- 
ized to  sign  contracts  for  the  landschaft  and  bank,  to  make 
entries  in  the  register  regarding  the  loans,  mortgages  and 
other  conveyances,  and  to  certify  documents  relative  to  pay- 
ments and  cancellations.  They  act  only  in  an  advisory 
capacity,  however,  unless  the  other  members  of  the  executive 
council  are  tied,  when  their  vote  decides. 
■■  The  executive  council  meets  weekly.  Its  duties  are  to 
enforce  the  laws,  rules  and  regulations,  to  guard  and  defend 
the  interests  of  the  landschaft,  to  supervise  the  bank,  the 
bureaus,  and  the  administration  of  the  funds  and  of  the 
entire  system  at  headquarters  and  in  the  districts,  and  espe- 
cially to  see  that  uniformity  of  business  methods  is  observed 
in  the  districts.  The  district  officials  must  submit  their 
accounts  to  the  executive  council  upon  request  and  carry  out 
the  resolutions  adopted  by  it. 

All  complaints  agaiast  the  district  boards  must  be  filed 
with  the  executive  council,  which  makes  its  decisions  upon 
reports  submitted  by  the  parties  or  by  investigating  commit- 
tees. The  executive  council  acts  as  a  court  of  first  instance 
in  disciplinary  proceedings  against  employees  of  the  land- 
schaft, as  well  as  against  all  officials  whose  appoiatment  is 
not  made  by  approval  of  the  King  or  the  Minister  of  Agricul- 
ture. Appeals  from  its  decisions  go  to  the  permanent  com- 
mittee but  the  decisions  of  the  executive  council  are  enforce- 
able until  set  aside. 

The  executive  council  does  not  receive  applications  for 
loans  or  attend  to  the  granting  of  credit.  But  all  the  deben- 
tures are  made  and  issued  by  it  in  its  own  name  and  appraisals 
of  properties  are  subject  to  its  revision;  hence  it  has  the 
power  to  order  a  reduction  in  the  amount  of  any  loan  con- 
sented to  by  a  district,  or  to  veto  it  entirely  by  refusing  to 
issue  debentures. 
'       II.  Each  district  has  a  board  composed  of  a  manager,  the 


,     SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  STEUCTUEE     4:9 

superintendents  of  the  circles  within  the  district,  and  one 
attorney.     Some  districts  have  two  managers. 

The  manager  is  elected  by  the  members  of  the  district, 
subject  to  the  approval  of  the  King.  He  must  own  a  mort- 
gaged estate  in  the  district,  be  well-to-do,  and  be  thoroughly 
familiar  with  farming  and  the  rules  and  regulations  of  the 
landschaft  relating  to  his  district,  and  have  served  formerly 
as  a  superintendent.  He  has  charge  of  the  business  of  his 
district  and  must  reside  the  greater  part  of  the  year  at  the 
place  selected  for  its  headquarters,  which  he-  must  not  leave 
without  notifying  the  executive  council.  He  calls  the  meet- 
ings of  the  district  board  and  presides  over  them,  but  has 
no  vote  except  in  case  of  a  tie.  He  has  wide  discretion  in 
the  exercise  of  his  powers  when  the  board  is  not  in  session. 

The  chief  duty  of  the  district  manager  is  to  administer 
the  properties  sequestered  or  foreclosed  upon,  but  he  cannot 
expend  any  money  on  them  except  to  prevent  imminent  loss 
which  it  is  not  possible  to  avoid  until  the  meeting  of  the  dis- 
trict board.  He  supervises  the  operation  of  the  branch  bank 
and  the  administration  of  the  funds  of  his  district.  He  has 
a  disciplinary  power  over  subordinates  but  can  remove  an 
ofBcial  only  upon  order  of  the  executive  council;  he  may 
suspend  him,  however,  and  send  a  report  on  the  case  forth- 
with to  the  executive  council.  He  is  required  to  keep  in 
close  touch  with  the  circles,  so  as  to  prevent  abuses  and 
wrongs  which  might  jeopardize  the  credit  of  the  association. 
Where  there  are  two  managers  in  a  district  they  alternate 
every  three  years,  so  that  only  one  exercises  power  at  a  time. 
The  supernumerary  is  a  member  of  the  district  board  and 
may  act  as  proxy  of  the  first.  In  some  districts  the  board 
appoints  a  proxy  manager  from  the  circle  superintendents. 
The  manager  draws  a  salary  and  is  allowed  traveling  ex- 
penses. ' 

All  circles  have  two  superintendents  and  the  larger  have 
three  or  four.  Superintendents  must  be  familiar  with  the 
constitution  and  by-laws  of  the  landschaft  and  thoroughly 
acquainted  with  conditions  in  their  circles.  A  superintendent 
need  not  live  within  his  circle.     Sometimes  even  a  man  whg 


50  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

has  no  farm  is  selected,  provided  he  inspires  confidence  and 
is  a  guardian  of  minors,  or  a  son  of  parents,  or  the  husband 
of  a  woman,  owning  an  estate  mortgaged  to  the  association  in 
the  circle.  A  superintendent,  however,  must  be  a  Gentile,  and 
the  land  which  he  owns  or  controls  be  free  of  litigation.  The 
only  excuses  for  not  serving  in  ease  of  election  are  that  he 
is  in  charge  of  some  estate,  or  is  a  member  of  some  com- 
mittee or  an  officer  intrusted  with  the  handling  of  fimds  of 
the  association,  or  has  already  served  a  term  as  superin- 
tendent. 

Besides  being  a  member  of  the  district  board,  the  superin- 
tendent must  watch  carefully  all  mortgaged  properties  and  see 
that  nothing  happens  to  impair  the  credit  and  well-being  of 
the  landschaft.  If,  for  example,  a  borrowing  member  culti- 
vates his  farm  in  a  shiftless  manner,  lets  his  live  stock  run 
down  or  his  buildings  get  out  of  repair,  or  contracts  bad 
habits,  it  is  the  duty  of  the  superintendent  to  report  the 
facts  to  the  district  manager,  who  has  full  power  to  order  an 
investigation  and  evict  the  delinquent. 

The  superintendents  are  usually  the  persons  commis- 
sioned by  the  district  board  or  executive  council  to  do  the 
field  work  relating  to  loans,  such  as  appraising  or  reapprais- 
ing estates,  collecting  debts,  and  administering  properties 
taken  over  for  the  settlement  of  claims.  The  ranking  superin- 
tendent convenes  the  meeting  of  his  circle,  and  aU  official 
conmnmieations  with  members  must  be  made  through  him. 
Superintendents  are  elected  by  their  respective  circles,  and 
are  given  per  diems  and  traveling  expenses. 

The  attorney  is  selected  by  the  superintendent  of  his  dis- 
trict. He  must  be  a  graduate  in  law.  His  position  is  per- 
manent and  he  draws  a  salary.  He  receives  his  instructions 
from  the  manager,  to  whom  he  gives  legal  advice  whenever 
requested;  he  conducts  lawsuits,  draws  contracts  and  other 
papers  connected  with  the  business  of  the  landschaft  in  the 
district,  and  makes  the  entries  regarding  the  loans  in  the 
district  register.  The  attorney  has  also  certain  duties  to  per- 
form in  the  branch  bank  and  in  supervising  the  district  funds. 
He  acts  as  lawyer,  notary  and  clerk  for  the  district  manage- 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  STEUCTURB      &1 

ment  and  as  secretary  to  the  district  board,  but  has  no  vote 
except  in  ease  of  a  tie. 

The  district  board  meets  usually  on  January  1  and  July  1 
of  each  year,  on  call  of  the  manager,  and  is  attended  by  one 
superintendent  from  each  circle  in  the  district.  Members 
are  allowed  to  be  present  as  spectators.  Action  is  taken  by  a 
majority  vote,  the  manager  having  no  voice  except  in  case 
of  a  tie. 

The  board  has  charge  of  the  affairs  and  funds  of  iiie  dis- 
trict. Within  its  area  its  powers  are  similar  to  those  of  the 
executive  council  over  the  whole  landschaf  t.  The  chief  duties 
of  the  board  are  to  pass  on  applications  for  loans,  appraise 
properties,  execute  loan  contracts,  receive  payments  from 
borrowers,  and  bring  the  necessary  proceedings  to  enforce 
recoveries  in  the  event  of  defaults.  It  has  power  also  to 
grant  extensions  and  to  order  the  recall  of  loans. 

III.  There  is  a  standing  committee  in  each  district  to 
attend  to  pressing  business  which  cannot  be  postponed  until 
the  next  meeting  of  the  board.  It  is  composed  of  the  dis- 
trict manager,  an  attorney,  and  two  to  four  superintendents 
who  are  selected  with  their  alternates  for  this  purpose  every 
six  months  at  the  district  meeting.  This  committee  is  con- 
vened by  the  district  manager  whenever  he  sees  fit,  for  the 
purpose  of  publishing  resolutions  of  the  district  and  circles, 
approving  appraisals,  granting  credit  when  quick  action  is 
required,  transferring  debentures,  examining  leases  of  mort- 
gaged properties  or  other  conveyances,  and  advancing  money 
to  manage  estates  under  forced  administration. 

IV.  The  final  authority  within  the  landschaft  is  the  gen- 
eral assembly.  This  is  not,  as  its  name  suggests,  a  meeting  of 
all  the  members  of  the  landschaft.  It  is  composed  of  the 
executive  council,  district  managers  and  attorneys,  and  two 
to  four  delegates  from  each  district  elected  by  the  members 
thereof.  It  is  presided  over  by  a  specially  appointed  royal 
commissioner  or,  in  his  absence,  by  the  president.  One  of  the 
counselors,  or,  if  neither  is  able  to  attend,  one  of  the  district 
attorneys,  acts  as  secretary  and  always  takes  the  chair  upon 
the  auditing  of  the  accounts.     Meetings   are   held  behind 


53  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

closed  doors ;  the  public  is  excluded  but  members  of  the  land- 
schaft  may  attend  as. spectators. 

The  assembly  has  no  stated  time  for  meeting.  It  is  con- 
vened only  on  extraordinary  occasions,  such  as  for  the  pur- 
pose of  amending  the  constitution  or  by-laws,  changing  busi- 
ness methods  or  objects,  borrowing  money,  or  authorizing  the 
use  of  the  funds  of  the  association  for  purposes  other  than 
those  for  which  they  have  been  created.  But  inasmuch  as 
its  authority  is  supreme,  officials  and  individual  members 
usually  submit  to  the  decision  of  the  assembly  various  proj- 
ects, questions,  complaints  and  appeals. 

The  assembly  is  called  by  the  executive  council  or  by  the 
permanent  committee.  When  it  decides  to  take  this  step,  the 
executive  council  notifies  the  government  and  orders  the 
members  to  elect  delegates.  As  soon  as  the  election  is  finished 
the  executive  council  fixes  the  date  for  the  meeting.  No  pro- 
posals can  be  submitted  to  the  assembly  except  those  which 
have  been  filed  beforehand  with  the  executive  council.  If 
the  circles  wish  to  bring  a  matter  before  the  assembly,  they 
must  send  it  to  the  executive  council  through  the  district 
board.  If  the  executive  council  is  in  doubt  or  disapproves, 
it  must  refer  the  matter  back  to  the  district  board  to  have 
the  circles  vote  upon  whether  it  should  be  sent  to  the  assem- 
bly. Also,  if  either  the  executive  council  or  the  permanent 
committee  originate  a  project  which  it  wishes  to  submit  to 
the  assembly,  the  same  procedure  must  be  followed  to  secure 
the  opinion  of  the  members. 

All  proposals  which  have  been  approved  by  the  circles  are 
referred  to  the  permanent  committee,  which  goes  over  them 
with  the  executive  council  to  decide  whether  they  should  be 
finally  submitted  to  the  assembly.  Voting  in  the  assembly 
is  by  groups,  and  motions  are  carried  by  a  majority  of  the 
votes.  The  delegates  of  each  district  under  their  manager 
form  a  group,  and  each  of  the  nine  groups  has  two  to  four 
votes,  depending  upon  the  size  of  the  district.  No  resolutions 
except  those  relating  to  the  internal  management  and  organi- 
zation of  the  landsehaft  are  valid  until  approved  by  the  king, 
and  all  resolutions  must  be  published  in  the  official  news- 


SILESIAN"  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  STEUCTUEB      53 

papers  and  duly  promulgated  to  the  district  boards  and  circle 
meetings  before  going  into  effect. 

V.  The  permanent  committee  is  in  a  measure  the  stand- 
ing representative  of  the  general  assembly.  It  was  instituted 
to  avoid  the  heavy  expenses  attendant  upon  holding  the 
assembly  and  because  of  the  difficulty  of  convening  it  at 
frequent  or  regular  intervals  on  account  of  the  cumbersome 
and  lengthy  procedure  of  the  call. 

The  permanent  committee  is  composed  of  the  district 
managers,  one  delegate  from  each  district  elected  by  the  resi- 
dent members,  and  the  executive  council.  The  president  of 
the  landschaft,  or  in  his  absence  the  first  vice-president,  acts 
as  chairman.  One  of  the  counselors  is  secretary,  or,  if  he  is 
unable  to  attend,  the  president  appoints  one  of  the  district 
attorneys  in  his  stead.  The  permanent  committee  convenes 
annually  during  March  or  April  at  a  day  fixed  by  the  execu- 
tive council.  A  second  meeting  may  be  called  if  business 
justifies  it.  The  district  managers  can  vote  only  upon  the 
amendment  of  an  old  rule  or  the  passage  of  a  new  one.  The 
executive  council  also  is  restricted  to  voting  on  legislative 
matters,  except  in  the  case  of  motions  upon  which  its  advice 
is  requested  or  by  which  its  former  decisions  are  put  in 
question. 

The  permanent  committee  receives  the  annual  report  of 
the  executive  council.  This  report  shows  the  loans  granted 
and  interest  rates  thereon,  the  debentures  issued  and  re- 
deemed, the  total  amount  of  the  outstanding  debentures  with 
market  quotations,  the  payments  made  by  borrowers,  the  over- 
due claims  and  measures  taken  to  enforce  them,  and  the  num- 
ber of  evictions  and  results  thereof,  besides  the  condition  of 
the  various  funds,  and  the  volume  of  business  done  with  non- 
members.  It  also  includes  the  fijaancial  statement  of  the 
bank. 

The  permanent  committee  examines  and  passes  on  the  ac- 
counts of  the  executive  council.  At  this  examination  the 
alternate  of  the  president  takes  the  chair,  and  a  district  attor- 
ney acts  as  secretary  in  place  of  a  counselor.  It  also  examines 
and  passes  on  the  accoimts  of  the  district  boards,  and  from 


54  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

the  reports  and  estimates  submitted  prepares  the  budget 
for  the  coming  year.  It  decides  appeals  from  the  decisions 
of  the  executive  council,  gives  opinions  in  doubtful  eases 
submitted  by  the  executive  coimcil,  and  announces  the  results 
of  all  elections.  Moreover,  it  determines  whether  proposals 
filed  with  the  executive  council  shall  be  referred  to  the  gen- 
eral assembly,  and  in  the  event  of  approval  may  call  a  meet- 
ing of  the  general  assembly  on  its  own  motion. 

VI.  The  larger  a  district  the  more  circles  it  has,  the 
aim  being  to  make  these  fundamental  administrative  units 
small  enough  to  assure  careful  attention  to  the  mortgaged 
properties  within  their  territories  and  to  all  the  details  of 
the  management  of  the  landschaft. 

The  circle  meetiags  are  held  semi-annually  in  January 
and  July,  upon  call  of  the  ranking  superintendent.  Extra 
calls  may  be  made  by  the  executive  council  or  district  boards. 
Fourteen  days'  notice  must  be  given,  stating  the  object  of 
the  meeting,  to  which  is  appended,  if  the  district  manager 
so  directs,  an  account  of  the  business  and  financial  condition 
of  the  landschaft  and  an  outline  of  the  minutes  of  the  last 
meetings  of  the  district  board  and  permanent  committee. 
The  notice  may  be  sent  by  registered  mail  if  covered  and 
sealed. 

Members  in  good  standing  who  are  not  in  default  on 
their  loans  may  vote  in  all  circles  in  which  they  own  property 
mortgaged  to  the  landschaft.  The  owner  of  four  to  seven 
farms  located  in  the  same  circle  may  cast  two  votes,  and  the 
owner  of  eight  or  more  farms,  three  votes  and  no  more.  At 
elections  a  member  has  but  one  vote  no  matter  how  many 
estates  he  may  own.  Voting  may  be  by  mail.  Proxies  are  not 
allowed  except  for  municipalities,  public  corporations,  com- 
panies, the  German  Emperor,  and  princes  of  the  Prussian 
royal  house.  Minors  and  women  must  be  represented  by 
proxies,  since  they  are  not  permitted  to  vote  in  person. 

The  jurisdiction  of  the  circle  meetings  extends  only  to 
matters  of  a  purely  local  nature,  questions  regarding  the  use 
of  the  district  funds  or  relating  to  the  raising  of  money  for 
the  needs  of  the  landschaft,  the  allowance  of  expenditures  in 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS   STRUCTUEE      55 

excess  of  estimates  in  the  budgets,  the  increase  of  salaries, 
the  creation  of  new  positions,  and  the  approval  of  proposals 
to  be  submitted  to  the  general  assembly.  It  has  nothing 
to  do  with  the  admission  or  expidsion  of  members  or  with  the 
granting  or  recalling  of  loans. 

The  usual  routine  at  a  circle  meeting  is  the  reading  of  a 
report  by  the  superintendent  on  events  of  interest  to  the  land- 
schaf t  and  reports  submitted  by  or  through  the  district  board ; 
annually  the  circle  receives  and  examines  the  budget  and  the 
accounts  of  the  finances  and  business  of  the  landsehaft.  When 
a  ballot  is  taken  for  any  purpose  a  majority  prevails.  If  it 
be  a  question  of  borrowiag  money  for  the  landsehaft,  the 
vote  of  a  majority  of  the  circles  gives  the  decision  of  the 
district,  and  the  vote  of  a  majority  of  the  districts  gives  the 
decision  of  the  landsehaft.  At  the  election  of  a  district  man- 
ager the  votes  of  the  various  circles  in  the  district  are  com- 
bined; where  there  are  three  or  more  candidates  the  plurality 
decides.  This  is  the  case  also  when  a  vote  is  taken  for  the 
whole  landsehaft. 

The  circle  meeting  is  the  only  place  where  members  can 
participate  in  the  management  of  the  landsehaft.  They  are 
allowed  no  part  in  the  general  assembly,  executive  coun- 
cil, in  the  boards  or  committees  of  the  districts;  hence  they 
have  not  as  much  power  as  shareholders  in  an  American  cor- 
poration. But  they  possess  the  right,  which  can  never  be  re- 
fused, to  have  their  properties  appraised  and  to  be  awarded 
debentures  up  to  a  certaiu  proportion  of  their  value  in  ex- 
change for  their  mortgage  contracts.  In  return  for  this,  how- 
ever, they  must  obey  orders  of  superiors  over  some  of  whom 
they  have  no  control,  and  stand  ready  to  perform  irksome 
duties  for  moderate  compensation  or  none  at  all. 

Members  are  bound  to  report  aU  negligence  or  tortious 
acts  of  neighbors  which  injure  their  farms  or  credit ;  and  in 
case  of  carelessness  in  this  particular,  or  if  they  fail  to  dis- 
charge their  duties  in  any  respect,  they  are  liable  to  warning 
and  even  arrest  by  the  authorities  of  the  landsehaft  and  finally 
to  expulsion.  Should  they  resist  or  use  violence  to  prevent 
the  execution  of  orders,  the  courts  will  intervene  in  a  sum- 


56  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

mary  way.  But  legal  proceedings  by  a  member  against  the 
landschaft  are  not  allowed;  he  must  abide  by  its  decisions. 
Appeals  from  the  decisions  of  the  district  boards  go  to  the 
executive  council,  and  then  to  the  permanent  committee. 

VII.  The  bank  of  the  Silesian  landschaft  was  organized 
under  a  special  act  in  1848  as  a  joint-stock  company  with 
about  $1,000,000  of  capital  all  supplied  from  the  funds  of  the 
districts.  The  executive  council  of  the  landschaft  is  the  super- 
vising head  of  the  bank,  and  appoints  two  of  its  three  man- 
agers. The  other  manager  is  appointed  by  the  permanent 
committee. 

The  officers  of  the  bank  are  considered  ofiScers  of  the 
landschaft  and  so  are  public  ofBcials.  They  cannot  be  re- 
moved except  for  cause.  They  must  obey  the  instructions  of 
the  executive  council  in  all  matters  relating  to  the  landschaft. 
In  dealings  with  other  parties  they  may  follow  their  own 
judgment  and  wishes.  The  counselors  of  the  landschaft  act 
as  attorneys  for  the  bank.  A  royal  commissioner  is  entitled 
to  attend  meetings  of  the  executive  council  when  it  sits  in 
committee  on  the  bank;  he  has  the  right  also  to  inspect  its 
books  and  accounts.  Eeports  must  be  rendered  every  three 
months,  and  oftener  if  required  by  the  council.  The  annual 
report  is  submitted  to  the  permanent  committee,  which  causes 
it  to  be  transmitted  to  the  district  boards. 

The  purpose  of  the  landschaft  in  founding  the  bank  was 
to  benefit  its  members,  to  create  a  safe  outlet  for  investing 
disposable  funds,  and  to  improve  farm  credit  facilities  in 
Silesia.  The  bank  receives  deposits,  discounts  and  accepts 
bankable  paper,  makes  loans  to  members  and  other  persons, 
and  accords  credit  on  accounts  current  covered  by  collateral. 
The  dividends  received  by  the  district  associations  are  applied 
to  the  reduction  of  expenses. 

The  bureaus  which  the  districts  conduct  for  according 
credit  to  resident  farmers  who  are  not  members  of  the  land- 
schaft were  organized  in  1849,  a  year  before  the  last  disabil- 
ities of  the  serfs  were  removed  by  the  law.  The  landschaft 
distributed  about  $175,600  among  the  districts  as  a  working 
and   guarantee   fund   for   this    business,    and    furthermore 


SILESIAN"  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS   STEUGTUEE      57 

agreed  to  assume  full  liability  until  this  fund,  increased  by 
its  earnings,  should  equal  five  per  cent  of  the  outstanding  de- 
bentures of  the  bureaus.  This  ratio  was  reached  in  1867, 
so  these  debentures,  denominated  'Tlfitera  D,"  are  no  longer 
a  charge  on  the  funds  or  members  of  the  landschaft.  Their 
security  rests  solely  upon  the  mortgages  of  non-members, 
backed  by  special  funds.  The  busiaess  of  the  bureau  is  kept 
separate  and  distiact  from  that  of  the  members'  association. 


CHAPTER  VII 

THE  SILESIAN  LANDSCHAPT:  ITS  OPEEATION 

Methods  of  Bank  and  of  Bureaus  for  Non-members. — Obligations  of 
Landsehaf  t. — Procedure  in  Obtaining  a  Loan. — ^Forms  of  Deben- 
tures Received:  litera  A  and  Litera  C. — Obligations  of  Bor- 
rowers.— Benefits  to  Members. — ^Eights  of  Borrowers. — ^Liabili- 
ties in  Case  of  Default. — Loans  to  Non-members. — Landsehaft 
Bank, 

The  bank  and  the  district  farm-mortgage  bureaus  for 
non-members  are  now  organic  parts  of  this  great  land-credit 
system  of  Silesia,  but  their  business  methods  are  quite  dif- 
ferent from  those  of  the  landsehaft  properly  so  called.  The 
bank  operates  with  its  own  resources  and  the  bureaus  operate 
against  special  funds;  neither  involves  the  members  of  the 
landsehaft  in  any  liability.  Moreover,  they  are  not  required 
to  accommodate  any  person  whom  they  do  not  wish  to  serve. 
Their  work  is  entirely  voluntary  and  discretionary. 

But  as  regards  the  true  landsehaft  in  the  system,  the'  obli- 
gations which  it  incurs  are  a  direct  charge  against  its  mem- 
bers or  funds,  while  every  Silesian  citizen  who  has  a  property 
of  the  kind  designated  by  the  orders  and  edicts  mentioned 
above,  has  a  right  as  a  matter  of  law  to  have  it  appraised 
and  himself  to  be  admitted  to  membership  in  the  association 
and  to  its  benefits;  and  when  once  a  member,  he  cannot 
be  expelled  nor  will  his  loan  be  recalled  so  long  as  he  obeys 
the  rules  and  regulations.  The  credit  which  must  be  accorded 
to  him  may  continue  practically  until  he  himself  is  willing 
or  able  to  relinquish  it. 

A  landowner  who  wishes  to  obtain  a  loan  as  a  member 
must  apply  to  the  office  of  the  landsehaft  in  the  district  in 
which  his  property  is  situated.     After  the  eligibility  of  the 

58 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAPT:  ITS  OPERATION      59 

property  is  determined  by  the  board  and  approved  by  the 
permanent  eommitteei  the  property  is  appraised.  The  net 
annual  profit  as  estimated  by  the  government  for  the  land 
tax,  multiplied  by  35,  less  certain  amoimts,  must  be  accepted 
for  the  value  if  satisfactory  to  the  owner.  If  the  owner  thinks 
this  value  too  low,  the  landschaft  must  proceed  to  a  special 
appraisement  at  his  expense.  This  is  made  by  a  committee 
appointed  by  the  district  manager,  consisting  of  the  district 
•  attorney,  the  superintendent  of  the  owner's  circle,  and  a  super- 
intendent of  another  circle. 

The  committee  examines  the  receipts  and  expenditures 
of  the  owner  for  the  preceding  six  years,  tests  the  soil  and 
subsoil,  inspects  the  live  stock  and  equipment,  and  ascertains 
the  annual  revenue  of  the  farm.  This  is  reckoned  in  bushels 
of  rye  for  arable  lands,  the  highest  calculation  being  48 
bushels  per  acre.  If  the  yield  is  less  than  11  bushels,  the  land 
is  rated  as  meadow  and  the  value  estimated  in  himdredweight 
of  hay.  If  the  yield  is  less  than  34  hundredweight  per  acre, 
the  land  is  considered  good  only  for  grazing,  and  the  value  is 
estimated  by  the  actual  hay  gains.  Garden  plots  are  valued 
by.^  their  actuali  gains. 

The  revenue  so  determined  is  then  multiplied  by  20  and 
reduced  six  or  ten  per  cent  or  even  more  if  the  live  stock  and 
equipment  are  insufficient.  For  each  two  to  four  acres  there 
should  be  one  head  of  kine,  or  two  to  four  foals,  or  ten  to 
15  sheep,  or  15  to  35  lambs.  For  each  37  or  40  acres  there 
should  be  four  horses  or  six  oxen.  The  final  estimate  is  com- 
pared with  the  price  at  which  the  land  was  bought,  and  if  the 
buildings  are  adequate  and  in  good  repair,  four-sixths,  i.  e., 
two-thirds,  of  the  value  of  the  property  is  taken  as  the  maxi- 
mum amoimt  that  the  ojvner  may  have  on  loan.  The  rules 
for  appraisals  were  made  by  the  general  assembly.  The  ap- 
praisers are  personally  responsible  to  the  landschaft,  but  not 
to  third  parties,  for  errors  and  false  returns.  Every  one  of  the 
numerous  details  of  the  rules  must  be  followed  carefully,  so 
the  work  is  slow  and  the  estimates  very  conservative. 

After  the  appraisal  has  been  passed  upon  by  two  other 
circle  superiatendents  and  approved  by  the  district  board, 


60 


EUEAL   CEEDITS 


the  mortgage  contract  is  drawn  up  and  submitted  with  all 
papers  to  the  executive  council  and  the  deal  is  closed.  But 
ordinarily  no  money  changes  hands.  The  credit  extended  is 
divided  into  two  parts,  one  equaling  three-sixths,  the  other 
equaling  one-sixth,  of  the  value  of  the  estate.    For  the  first 


Debenture  Bond  Litera  A. 


Series. 


No. 


The  Silesian  Landschaft's  Privileged 

Debenture  Bond  Lixera  A. 

of Marks 

German  gold  coin  and  three  and  one-half 
per  cent  interest  per  year. 

Issued  in  accordance  with  the  regula- 
tion of  January  22,  1872. 

Based  on  a  mortgage  of  equal  amount 
and  on  the  general  guarantee  of  all  the 
members. 

Kedeemable  and  payable  by  the  Land- 
scbaft,  but  not  subject  to  the  call  of  the 
bearer. 

Breslau,  the    •  day  of  19    . 

[Seal] 

Silesian  General  Landschafi  Directorate 

Eegistered  in  the  debenture  bond  reg- 
ister, volimie. . .  .page. . . . 

Certified  by Counselor 

President. 


.Marks 


With  the  de- 
benture bond  in- 
terest coupons 
have  been  issued 
for  the  current 
period  and  a  re- 
newal coupon  for 
the  following  pe- 
riod. 

Interest  and 
renewal  coupons 
are  renewed  peri- 
odically after  the 
last  renewal  cou- 
pon has  been  re- 
turned by  the 
bearer.  (I,  6,  of 
regulat  i  on  of 
Jan.  22,  1872.) 


part  the  borrower  receives  debentures  denominated  "Litera 
A."  These  are  direct  obligations  of  the  central  administra- 
tion and  also  a  direct  charge  against  a  mass  of  mortgages  on 
properties  always  double  the  value  of  the  debentures  by  reason 
of  this  arrangement;  hence  Lit.  A.  debentures  are  quoted 
highest  of  all.  For  the  second  part  he  receives  debentures 
denonunated  "Litera  C."    These  are  direct  obligations  of  the 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  OPEEATION      61 

district  and  their  lien  is  subordinate  to  that  of  the  others; 
hence  their  quotations  are  lower  and  they  are  taken  only 
when  the  borrower  wishes  to  ntUize  his  credit  to  its  full  ex- 
tent and  encumber  his  land  to  two-thirds  its  value. 

Both  kinds  of  debentures,  however,  are  executed  by  the 

Debenture  Bond  Litera  C. 


Series. 


No. 


The  SttESiAN  Landschaft's  Privileged 

Debenture  Bond  Lftera  C. 

of Marks 

German  gold  coin  and  three  and  one-half 
per  cent  interest  per  year. 

Issued  in  accordance  with  the  regula- 
tion of  November  22,  1858;  October  6, 
1868,  and  October  30,  1872.  Based  on  a 
reserve  fund,  a  mortgage  of  equal 
amount  and  the  Special  Funds  of  the 
Landschaft.  Redeemable  and  payable 
by  the  Landschaft,  but  not  subject  to  the 
call  of  the  bearer. 

Breslau,  the  day  of  19    . 

[Seal] 

Silesian  General  Landschaft  Directorate 

Registered  in  the  debenture  bond  reg- 
ister, volume. . .  .page 

Certified  by Counselor 

President. 


executive  council  and  are  legal  claims  against  the  entire  land- 
schaft. They  alike  bear  four,  three  and  one-half,  or  three 
per  cent  interest.  Five  per  cent  debentures  are  allowed  but  it 
has  not  been  necessary  to  issue  any  of  them  since  1872.  The 
borrower  chooses  whichever  rate  he  pleases,  his  choice  of 
course  depending  upon  the  condition  of  the  money  market. 


62  ETJEAL   CEBDITS 

The  rate  chosen  nmst  exactly  correspond  with  the  rate  of  his 
loan.  He  sells  the  debentures  at  the  bank  of  the  landschaft 
or  wherever  he  can  get  the  best  price,  and  thus  obtaias  the 
money  for  which  he  has  mortgaged  his  land.  If  he  be  unable 
to  dispose  of  his  debentures  at  par,  the  manager  of  the  dis- 
trict may  grant  him  a  cash  loan  at  four  per  cent  equal  to  the 
difference  between  the  market  quotation  and  the  face  value, 
but  this  sum  must  never  exceed  six  per  cent  of  the  face  value. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  landschaft  always  gives  cash  for  the 
full  amount  of  the  loan  whenever  the  debentures  are  quoted 
above  par  at  the  time  the  mortgage  is  taken.  These  are  the 
only  instances  when  loans  are  realized  in  money. 

In  return  for  these  debentures  the  borrower  obligates 
himself  to  pay  their  interest  and  one-half  of  one  per  cent  of 
their  principal  a  year  for  their  amortization,  and  an  addi- 
tional one-sixth  of  one  per  cent  to  cover  the  cost  of  business. 
If  he  utilizes  his  entire  credit,  he  becomes  obligated  to  pay 
one-twelfth  of  one  per  cent  more  to  cover  the  cost  of  business 
and  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  to  the  district  for  16  years 
as  a  reserve  for  Litera  C  debentures.  These  contributions  are 
combined  with  the  interest  to  form  an  annuity  payable  in 
semi-annual  instalments.  He  furthermore  agrees  to  pay  the 
principal  in  lump  on  six  months'  notice,  pay  four  per  cent 
interest  on  arrears,  and  abide  by  the  constitution  and  rules  of 
the  association.  The  borrower  pays  the  stamp  tax  and  regis- 
tration fees,  whereupon  his  contract  and  mortgage  are  duly 
filed  in  the  public  registration  office  and  transcripts  thereof  at 
headquarters  and  in  the  district.  Only  first  mortgages  on 
land  entirely  free  of  other  encumbrance  are  taken. 

The  borrower's  contract  does  not  specify  or  fix  the  period 
during  which  the  annuity  shall  be  paid.  It  requires  him  to 
pay  the  full  annuity  as  long  as  he  remains  a  member  of  the 
association,  consequently  the  amount  of  his  interest  and  dues 
continue  the  same  each  year  until  his  loan  has  been  entirely 
extinguished.  At  present  the  borrower  does  not  pay  any 
contribution  to  the  cost  of  business  on  Litera  A  debentures, 
while  on  Litera  C  debentures  the  contribution  is  fixed  at  one- 
tenth  of  one  per  cent  and  it  is  collected  in  only  five  of  the 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  OPERATION      63 

districts.  The  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  on  Litera  C  de- 
bentures also  has  been  discontinued.  The  reason  is  that  the 
regular  income  of  the  landschaf t  is  sufficient  to  meet  current 
expenses  and  the  funds  of  the  districts  have  reached  the  maxi- 
mum required  by  law,  but  the  payment  to  cover  the  cost  of 
business  is  automatically  restored  if  expenditures  run  over 
receipts,  while  the  additional  payment  on  Litera  C  deben- 
tures may  be  restored  at  any  time  by  resolution  of  the  per- 
manent committee.  Borrowers  now  pay  only  one-half  of  the 
costs  of  special  appraisals. 

Every  profit  or  saving  inures  to  the  members.  They  enjoy 
the  lowest  interest  rates  because  the  landschaft,  being  com- 
posed of  the  members  themselves,  has  no  object  in  making 
gaia  out  of  them.  In  all  probability  they  will  never  be  pressed 
for  the  repayment  of  the  principal,  since  only  a  national 
calamity  would  oblige  the  landschaf t  to  exercise  the  right  it 
has  reserved  for  calliag  in  the  loans.  There  are  other  advan- 
tages not  obtainable  from  ordinary  lenders.  If  a  borrower 
cannot  pay  his  annuity  the  district  manager  will  give  him  a 
respite  until  the  next  meeting  of  the  district  board,  upon  a 
written  request  sent  14  days  before  the  time  set  for  payment, 
if  the  cause  of  the  trouble  is  certified  to  by  the  superintendent 
of  the  circle.  The  board  may  extend  the  time  for  six  months, 
while  the  permanent  committee  has  the  power  to  enact  stay 
laws  for  a  district  or  the  entire  landschaft  in  the  event  of  an 
overwhelming  necessity.  But  such  favors  are  possible  of 
course  only  when  the  landschaft  has  funds  on  hand  sufficient 
to  meet  the  interest  on  outstanding  debentures. 

Although  the  landschaft  may  never  recall  or  alter  the 
credit  it  extends,  the  borrower  has  the  right  to  have  his  in- 
terest reduced  if  he  can  get  a  better  rate,  and  also  to  make 
advance  payments  on  the  principal  in  whole  or  in  part,  using 
either  cash  or  debentures  for  this  purpose.  The  reduction 
of  the  interest  is  effected  by  redeeming  outstanding  deben- 
tures at  the  member's  request  and  issuing  to  him  in  their 
stead  new  ones  of  a  lower  rate.  But  the  transaction  is  made 
at  the  member's  expense  and  he  must  put  up  a  three  per  cent 
margin  in  cash  or  debentures  to  secure  the  landschaft  against 


64  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

any  loss  if  he  shoulcl  fail  to  complete  the  deal.  The  reduction 
of  the  principal  is  accomplished  in  the  same  way.  The  bor- 
rower buys  debentures  in  the  market  and  turns  them  in  to 
the  association  as  so  much  cash;  or  else  he  pays  cash  and  the 
landsehaft  buys  the  necessary  debentures  for  him,  or  calls  in 
the  required  amount  for  redemption.  Three  months'  notice 
of  cash  payments  and  seven  months'  notice  of  payments  by 
debentures  must  be  given  in  order  that  the  association  may 
have  time  to  purchase  them  or  to  take  the  regular  steps  for 
their  redemption. 

The  borrower  has  also  certain  rights  in  the  amortization 
fund,  created  by  the  instalments  paid  by  borrowers  on  their 
debenture  loans.  When  his  payments  into  this  fund  for 
Litera  A  debentures  equal  one-tenth  of  his  debt,  he  may  have 
his  mortgage  cancelled  to  that  extent,  or  he  may  take  out  a 
new  loan  for  the  amount,  or  use  it  as  a  current  account  at  the 
landsehaft  bank.  The  manager  of  the  district  decides  whether 
this  privilege  shall  be  granted.  Moreover,  to  save  the  mem- 
ber from  the  temptation  of  spending  it,  the  district  manager, 
at  his  request,  will  make  a  note  on  the  registers  that  the 
amount  is  barred  from  further  use  by  the  borrower  imtU  his 
entire  loan  has  been  paid.  The  borrower's  share  in  this  fund 
can  never  be  attached  by  third  parties.  He  cannot  touch  it 
himself  imtil  it  reaches  the  proportion  mentioned,  and  so 
long  as  it  remains  in  the  landsehaft  it  belongs  to  the  farm 
and  passes  with  it  to  any  new  owner. 

If  the  member  defaults  his  annuity  or  does  or  fails  to  do 
any  act  in  violation  of  his  contract  to  the  injury  or  jeopardy 
of  his  credit,  and  no  extension  or  remission  has  been  granted, 
his  mortgaged  estate  becomes  immediately  subject  to  the  con- 
trol of  the  landsehaft.  The  landsehaft,  without  order  of  court 
or  formality  of  law,  may  seize  and  sell  at  auction  the  farm 
products  on  hand,  the  live  stock  or  any  of  the  personal  prop- 
erty, or  sequester  the  estate  in  whole  or  in  part  and  lease  or 
operate  it  in  its  own  behalf.  This  may  be  done  also  if  the 
security  becomes  impaired  even  through  no  fault  of  the  mem- 
ber. But  leniency  is  always  shown  to  the  delinquent  and  every 
effort  is  made  to  restore  him  to  possession  as  soon  as  arrears 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAPT:  ITS  OPERATION      65 

are  collected.  In  the  meantime  a  portion  of  the  property  is 
usually  left  him  to  live  on. 

The  manager  of  the  district  has  powers  as  judge  and 
sheriff  in  such  a  proceeding.  He  must  see  that  the  lessee 
agrees  to  abide  by  the  rules  of  the  landschaft  if  the  estate 
is  leased.  If  he  decides  to  operate  the  estate,  he  designates 
some  circle  superintendent  as  trustee  or  receiTer.  The  super- 
intendent appoints  some  borrowing  member  who  owns  a  mort- 
gaged farm  in  the  neighborhood  as  overseer.  Acceptance  of 
this  appointment  is  obligatory.  Should  the  person  appointed 
refuse  to  serve  without  being  excused  by  the  board  of  the  dis- 
trict, he  is  liable  for  any  loss  that  may  have  occurred.  His 
duties  are  to  supervise  the  sequestered  farm,  attend  to  the 
receipts  and  expenditures,  and  render  a  report  to  the  board 
once  a  year  or  oftener.  He  may  or  may  not  be  paid.  The 
circle  superintendent  also  hires  a  trustworthy  farmer  of  ex- 
perience to  do  the  agricultural  work  under  the  supervision  of 
the  overseer,  who  submits  monthly  reports  to  him.  A  mem- 
ber may  be  compelled  to  work  the  land. 

If  the  arrears  of  the  delinquent  member  cannot  be  recov- 
ered by  means  of  this  sequestration,  the  landschaft  may  apply 
to  the  courts  to  have  the  mortgaged  estate  sold.  This  is  not 
a  foreclosure  suit.  It  is  a  swift  and  summary  proceeding,  but 
notice  of  bringing  it  must  be  duly  published.  The  landschaft 
does  not  have  to  offer  any  evidence  except  its  registers  and 
records.  The  entries  therein,  showing  the  title  of  the  prop- 
erty, the  execution  of  the  mortgage  and  the  debt  of  the  owner, 
must  be  accepted  by  the  court  as  proof.  The  court's  sole 
province  is  to  determine  the  authenticity  of  these  documents, 
and  if  they  are  found  to  be  genuine,  it  must  render  judgment 
against  the  defendant  and  order  the  sale  demanded  by  the 
landschaft.  A  third  party  cannot  intervene  in  the  proceeding. 
If  he  feels  aggrieved  his  only  recourse  is  a  direct  suit  against 
the  landschaft  for  damages. 

The  sale  is  made  at  auction  by  the  public  administrator. 
The  landschaft  remains  in  charge  until  the  new  owner  takes 
possession.  It  may  bid  in  the  property  to  protect  its  claim 
and  hold  it  for  one  -year  without  paying  the  transfer  tax  pre- 


66  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

scribed  by  tbe  general  law.  If  it  cannot  resell  within  that 
time,  it  may  pay  one-twelfth  of  the  taz  in  the  second  year 
and  the  balance  in  the  third  year.  But  it  cannot  hold  per- 
manently any  real  estate  of  a  value  exceeding  $1,300  without 
the  consent  of  the  Minister  of  Agriculture. 

No  member  of  the  association  who  has  had  any  duty  con- 
nected with  the  ease  can  acquire  the  estate  by  purchase  until 
three  years  after  the  sale.  If  the  proceeds  are  more  than 
enough  to  satisfy  the  judgment,  the  surplus  is  turned  over 
to  the  defendant.  If  they  are  insufficient,  the  landschaft  may 
appropriate  his  share  in  the  amortization  fund  to  make  up  the 
deficiency.  Any  balance  in  this  fund  is  then  given  to  the 
new  owner  of  the  property.  The  membership  of  the  debtor 
ceases  with  these  proceedings  and  his  credit  is  abrogated. 

Non-members  who  are  accorded  the  credit  facilities  of  the 
district  bureaus  must  give  their  consent  in  writing  to  the 
use  of  these  special  summary  proceedings  against  them,  and 
must  agree  also  to  obey  iustructions  issued  by  the  officials  of 
the  landschaft.  Appraisals  of  the  property  of  a  non-member 
are  made  by  the  same  rules  in  force  for  members.  Two-thirds 
of  its  value  is  the  maximum  credit  allowed.  Bach  district  has 
two  or  more  permanently  employed  and  salaried  appraisers 
elected  by  a  committee  composed  of  the  manager,  attorney 
of  the  district  and  a  superintendent  from  each  circle.  These 
appraisers  need  not  be  members.  The  committee  conducts  the 
business  of  the  bureau. 

The  loans  to  non-members  are  all  made  in  debentures. 
These  Litera  D  debentures  now  bear  3.5  per  cent  interest. 
The  executive  council  has  authority,  however,  to  issue  them 
at  three,  four,  four  and  one-half,  and  five  per  cent,  but  an 
order  must  be  obtained  from  the  permanent  committee  for 
the  five  per  cents.  Sums  which  may  be  evenly  divided  by  $34 
may  be  paid  on  the  loan  in  advance.  Debentures  of  the  land- 
schaft may  be  used  for  this  purpose. 

All  loans  to  non-members  are  recallable  on  six  months' 
notice,  and  are  repayable  by  annuities  of  four  and  one-tenth 
of  one  per  cent,  in  semi-annual  instalments.  Of  this  amount, 
3.5  per  cent  pays  the  interest  on  the  debentures,  one-tenth  goes 


SILESIAN  LANDSCHAFT:  ITS  OPERATION      67 

to  cover  the  cost  of  business,  and  one-half  of  one  per  cent 
is  placed  in  the  amortization  fund.  The  borrower  has  rights 
in  this  fund  similar  to  those  of  members,  when  his  share 
equals  one-foiirth  of  the  principal  of  his  debt.  No  extensions 
of  over  six;  months  are  allowed. 

The  landschaft  bank  does  not  make  loans  on  real  estate. 
Its  chief  object  is  to  serve  as  the  depositary  of  the  funds  of 
the  landschaft,  act  as  its  financial  agent,  and  facilitate  the 
circulation  of  its  debentures.  It  makes  loans  to  holders  of 
these  debentures  up  to  85  per  cent  of  their  face  value,  and  also 
accords  credit  to  borrowers  from  the  landschaft  against  their 
free  balances  in  the  amortization  fund.  Farmers  may  obtain 
loans  from  the  bank  up  to  two-thirds  the  value  of  pledged 
agricultural  products  of  a  not  easily  perishable  nature.  The 
bank  has  not  been  given  any  privileges  in  the  way  of  special 
proceedings  for  recovering  its  claims.  It  transacts  its  busi- 
ness as  an  ordinary  banking  company  imder  the  general  laws. 


CHAPTEE  VIII 

THE    SILESIAN    LANDSCHAFT:    ITS    FUNDS    AND 
DEBENTURES 

Investment  of  Interest. — General  Fund. — Amortization  Fund. — Guar- 
anty Fund. — ^Bank  Fund. — ^Accounts. — ^Reports. — ^Denominations 
of  Debentures. — Debentures  Only  in  Exchange  for  Mortgage 
Contracts. — Eights  of  Debenture  Holders. — Redemption  of  De- 
bentures on  Eepayment  of  Loan. — Debentures  as  Investments. — 
Litera  B  Debentures. — Condition  of  Silesian  Landschaft  in  1912. 

Dates  of  payment  are  so  fixed  that  mortgagors  pay  inter- 
est on  their  loans  six  months  before  it  is  turned  over  to 
holders  of  the  debentures.  This  is  done  to  give  ample  time 
to  enforce  collection  in  the  event  of  default.  The  interest 
is  deposited  at  interest  in  the  landschaft  bank  as  received  and 
drawn  out  as  needed.  All  other  moneys  are  invested  in  the 
landschaff  s  own  debentures.  No  other  form  of  investment  is 
allowed.  Speculation  is  prohibited  and  no  real  or  personal 
property  may  be  owned  by  the  landschaft  beyond  what  is 
necessary  to  its  existence.  Since  its  funds  are  thus  kept  in 
its  ovm  debentures  and  loans  are  made  in  the  same  way,  the 
operations  of  the  landschaft  are  represented  by  its  own  paper 
and  very  little  cash  is  required  for  carrying  on  its  business. 
The  annuities  of  borrowers  are  split  up  into  their  component 
parts  and  distributed  among  the  various  fimds  to  which  they 
belong.  Other  payments  of  borrowers  and  all  receipts  and 
disbursements  of  the  landschaft  are  similarly  disposed  of,  so 
the  money  goes  out  by  retiring  debentures,  or  making  new 
loans  shortly  after  it  is  paid  back  by  the  borrowers,  and  is 
continually  in  motion. 

The  portion  of  the  annuities  which  is  assessed  for  the  cost 
of  business  is  placed  in  the  general  funds  of  the  districts. 

68 


SILESIAN   LANDSCHAFT:   ITS   FUNDS        69 

The  maximum  assessment  of  one-sixth  of  one  per  cent  must  be 
maiutained  untU  the  income  from  this  source  suffices  to  pay 
seven-twelfths  of  the  district  expenses.  After  that  point  is 
reached,  it  may  be  reduced,  provided  $300  is  always  left  in 
the  general  funds  for  every  $1,000,000  of  debentures  in  cir- 
culation. The  same  rule  applies  for  the  maximum  of  one- 
twelfth  of  oiie  per  cent  for  Litera  C  debentures. 

The  central  management  and  each  district  has  a  general 
fund.  That  of  the  central  management  was  started  with  the 
grants  of  Frederick  the  Great.  Two  per  cent  of  the  revenue 
of  these  old  grants  is  devoted  to  pensions  for  oflBcers  and  their 
families.  The  rest  goes  into  the  general  fund,  as  do  also 
unclaimed  debentures  and  coupons,  various  fees,  such  as 
charges  for  registering  debentures  and  appraising  properties 
of  third  parties  whose  applications  for  membership  have  been 
rejected,  incidental  gains,  the  earnings  of  these  accumulations, 
and  lastly  sums  borrowed  from  the  outside  in  case  of  necessity. 
Out  of  the  general  fund  of  the  central  management  are  paid 
such  expenses  as  losses  on  defaulted  mortgages,  expenditures 
on  sequestered  estates  which  secure  latera  A  debentures, 
allowances  and  salaries  of  the  ofBcers  and  employees  of  the 
general  stafE,  the  cost  of  the  upkeep  of  its  buildings,  and  the 
purchase  of  supplies. 

The  expenses  paid  from  the  general  funds  of  the  districts 
are  such  as  are  connected  with  their  particular  parts  of  the 
business  of  the  landschaft.  The  district  general  funds  are 
maintained  by  the  one-sixth  of  one  per  cent  commission  on 
Litera  A  debentures,  the  extra  one-twelfth  of  one  per  cent 
charged  members  who  receive  Litera  C  debentures,  dividends 
from  the  landschaft  bank,  various  gains,  and  whatever  appro- 
priations may  be  made  by  the  executive  council  or  permanent 
committee.  The  TniTiimuTii  for  the  size  of  these  fimds  is  the 
same  as  that  of  the  central  fund,  $200  for  each  $1,000,000 
of  debentures  in  circulation.  This  has  been  reached  in  four 
districts;  hence  only  five  districts  continue  the  extra  assess- 
ment for  Litera  C  debentures. 

The  portion  of  the  annuities  which  are  paid  by  members 
for  the  reduction  of  principal  are  placed  in  their  correspond- 


70  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

ing  amortization  funds  for  Literae  A,  C  and  D  debentures. 
The  first  source  of  these  funds  is  the  obligatory  one-half  of 
one  per  cent  paid  by  all  borrowers ;  they  include  also  voluntary 
payments  and  all  profits  and  unneeded  surpluses  of  other 
funds.  For  Litera  C  debentures  is  added  the  one-fourth  of 
one  per  cent  paid  for  16  years  by  mortgagors  who  borrow  up 
to  the  limit  of  credit. 

For  Litera  D  debentures  a  special  guaranty  fund,  as  well 
as  a  special  amortization  fund,  has  been  created.  In  general 
the  annuities  of  non-members  go  into  the  latter,  but  one  dis- 
trict retains  one-tenth  of  the  annuity  to  compensate  itself 
for  its  trouble  and  expense ;  in  all  other  districts  the  one-tenth 
goes  into  the  guaranty  fund.  This  guaranty  fund  was  started 
in  1849  by  $171,600  set  aside  for  that  purpose  by  the  central 
management  and  distributed  among  the  districts.  The  profits 
of  the  business  in  aU  except  the  one  district  mentioned  have 
been  added  to  it  for  many  years.  These  two  funds  must  be 
invested  in  debentures  of  the  landschaft;  for  this  purpose  all 
three  classes  of  debentures  are  eligible. 

The  payments  for  the  outstanding  debentures  issued  in 
the  original  form  for  the  earliest  loans  are  turned  into  the 
funds  of  the  central  management. 

The  operations  of  the  landschaft  bank  are  secured  by  its 
capital  stock  and  a  reserve  to  which  15  per  cent  of  the  earn- 
ings is  added  each  year. 

A  separate  account  in  the  amortization  funds  is  kept  for 
every  borrower  and  to  it  are  credited  all  payments  he  makes 
and  his  share  of  the  profits.  It  is  debited  with  withdrawals, 
defaults  and  expenses  which  he  has  caused  the  landschaft,  to- 
gether with  his  share  of  the  losses  sustained  by  the  landschaft. 
This  account  is  balanced  every  six  months.  Although  it  runs 
with  the  land  and  does  not  belong  to  the  borrower  personally, 
the  landschaft  bank  will  grant  him  a  loan  against  it  if  he  is 
in  good  standing,  while  the  district  manager  will  allow  him 
the  privilege  of  using  it  in  the  ways  already  indicated. 

The  cancellation  of  the  borrower's  mortgage  is  made  as 
a  matter  of  course  when  his  credit  account  in  the  amortiza- 
tion fund  equals  his  debt.    But  if  a  member  should  request 


SILESIAlf   LANDSCHAPT:    ITS    FUNDS        71 

that  his  balance  be  left  in  the  treasury,  the  landsehaft  will 
accord  him  credit  anew  without  examining  his  qualifications 
for  membership  or  reappraising  his  property.  This  privi- 
lege is  limited  to  one  year.  The  landsehaft  is  able  to  do 
this  without  risk  because  it  keeps  itself  fully  informed  of  any 
deterioration  of  the  properties  or  change  in  the  condition  of 
members.  Siace  the  amortizing  contributions  of  members 
must  all  be  invested  in  debentures  of  the  same  series  and 
interest  rates  as  members  received  for  their  mortgages,  com- 
pound interest  runs  in  their  favor  to  hasten  the  extinction  of 
the  loans. 

Brief  statements  regarding  all  funds  must  be  forwarded 
by  the  executive  council  and  the  district  boards  to  the  circles 
for  their  information  at  their  January  meetings.  Complete 
reports,  together  with  estimates  of  expenses  for  the  coming 
year,  must  be  rendered  to  the  permanent  committee  in  time 
for  the  committee  with  the  executive  council  to  prepare  the 
annual  budget  therefrom  to  be  sent  by  April  1  to  the  circles 
for  approval.  The  largest  sum  which  may  be  expended  in 
excess  of  the  budget  is  $108  for  a  district  board  and  $216 
for  the  executive  council.  Pajrments  of  borrowers  for  the 
difEerent  funds  may  be  received  by  the  landsehaft  bank  or  at 
headquarters,  but  as  a  rule  they  are  made  at  the  offices  of  the 
districts,  and  the  districts  place  the  portion  belonging  to  the 
central  management  to  its  account  at  the  landsehaft  bank 
every  six  months. 

The  King  of  Prussia  has  the  power  to  order  the  landsehaft 
to  allow  members  to  withdraw  their  entire  balances  in  the 
amortization  funds.  This  power  was  exercised  during  the 
financial  disturbances  in  1848,  1855,  and  1904.  In  the  wars 
of  1812-14  Napoleon  confiscated  aU  funds  for  military  pur- 
poses and  so  upset  the  calculations  made  for  the  extinguish- 
ment of  the  loans.  The  state  can  divert  any  of  the  funds 
from  their  regular  use  but  no  creditor  of  a  member  may 
touch  them. 

Debentures  are  payable  by  the  landsehaft,  but  are 
drawn  without  any  fixed  period  of  maturity.  They  particu- 
larly state  that  they  are  not  subject  to  recall  by  the  holder. 


72  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

but  are  redeemable  only  at  the  will  of  the  landschaft.  They 
are  made  in  series  and  indicate  on  their  face  the  fimds  and 
classes  of  securities  back  of  them.  The  denominations  of 
Literse  A  and  C  debentures  run  from  $24  up  to  $720;  of 
litera  D  debentures  from  $24  up  to  $1,200,  and  are  drawn 
payable  to  bearer  or  in  the  name  of  the  holders  as  the  bor- 
rower prefers.  Coupons  are  attached  for  ten  years'  interest 
and  a  "talon"  or  certificate  entitling  the  holder  to  another 
set  of  coupons  and  a  talon. 

The  landschaft  does  not  keep  any  debentures  on  hand 
for  sale  to  the  public.  They  are  disposed  of  only  in  exchange 
for  mortgage  contracts.  The  effect  of  this  exchange  is  that 
a  borrower  divides  his  loan  into  a  number  of  convenient  parts 
which  may  be  easily  sold  anywhere  in  Germany,  because  the 
Silesian  landschaft  has  a  national  reputation  and  the  holders 
of  the  debentures  know  that  the  provincial  government  con- 
nected with  it  will  protect  their  rights. 

The  holder  of  a  debenture  is  entitled  to  the  payment  of 
interest  at  various  designated  places  in  the  Empire,  and  also 
to  the  payment  of  the  principal  when  the  debenture  is  called 
for  redemption.  If  the  landschaft  should  default,  the  holder 
of  a  litera  A  debenture  may  bring  suit  and  ask  the  courts 
for  a  recovery  out  of  the  mortgages  acquired  at  the  issue  of 
its  series,  and  then  out  of  the  collective  liability  of  the  mem- 
bers. But  neither  of  the  other  classes  of  debentures  is  a 
charge  against  this  liability  of  the  members.  The  holder  of 
a  Litera  C  debenture  may  ask  for  a  recovery  out  of  its  amor- 
tization fund,  then  out  of  the  mortgage  of  its  series,  and 
finally  out  of  the  general  fund  of  the  district  in  which  these 
mortgages  were  taken.  The  holder  of  a  Litera  D  debenture 
may  ask  for  recovery  out  of  its  amortization  fund,  then  out 
of  the  special  guaranty  fimd,  and  then  out  of  the  mortgages 
of  the  non-member  borrowers  of  the  issuing  bureau. 

Every  settlement  of  a  loan  by  voluntary  payment  of  the 
borrower  or  by  legal  proceedings  requires  the  redemption 
of  a  corresponding  amoiont  of  debentures  of  the  kind  iq  which 
the  loan  was  made.  The  face  value  of  the  debentures  in  cir- 
culation must  never  exceed  the  unpaid  principal  of  the  out- 


SILESIAN"   LANDSCHAPT:    ITS    FUNDS        73 

standing  loans.  The  landschaft  is  compelled  each  year  to 
make  a  report  to  the  government  on  its  loan  and  debenture 
operations,  and  a  royal  commissioner  appointed  to  superTise 
the  landschaft  sees  that  they  properly  balance  one  another. 

The  landschaft  obtains  the  debentures  it  wishes  to  redeem 
either  by  purchase  at  the  bourse  or  by  calling  them  in  by 
■drawing  lots.  The  caU  must  be  announced  in  the  official 
newspapers  of  Berlin  and  Breslau  and  notices  of  it  must  be 
posted  in  the  bourses  of  those  cities  and  at  aU  offices  of  the 
landschaft  and  its  bank.  The  debentures  to  be  withdrawn 
must  be  specified  by  numbers,  series  and  interest  rates.  Pur- 
chased debentures  need  not  be  listed  in  the  call. 

When  the  debentures  are  thus  recalled  they  are  consid- 
ered as  matured  and  the  interest  stops  running.  The  land- 
schaft sets  aside  a  sufficient  sum  to  redeem  the  recalled  de- 
l)entures  and  holds  it  at  two  per  cent  interest  or  invests  it  in 
■other  debentures  for  the  owners.  Coupons  not  presented 
within  four  years  and  debentures  not  redeemed  within  30 
years  become  null  and  void  and  are  forfeited  to  the  general 
fund  of  the  central  management.  Provision  is  made  for 
issuing  duplicates  for  debentures  which  have  been  damaged 
or  proved  to  have  been  lost  or  destroyed.  Both  coupons  and 
debentures  payable  to  bearer  may  be  registered  in  the  name 
of  the  owner  without  any  charge.  Debentures  may  be  de- 
posited with  the  landschaft  for  safekeeping  and  exchanged 
for  a  registered  receipt  for  a  small  fee.  Eedeemed  debentures 
can  never  be  restored  to  circulation.  They  are  cut  with  scis- 
sors, marked  vrith  a  cancellation  stamp,  and  burned  after  three 
years.  The  debentures  of  all  classes  of  the  Silesian  land- 
schaft are  lawful  investments  for  funds  of  savings  banks,  in- 
surance companies,  public  corporations,  trustees,  executors  and 
guardians. 

There  appears  to  be  a  class  lacking  among  the  kinds  of 
debentures  described.  The  omission  is  only  apparent.  No  de- 
bentures were  ever  issued  which  might  have  been  denominated 
"Litera  B."  The  absence  of  this  letter  explains  an  historic 
incident  which  discloses  the  defects  of  the  Silesian  land-credit 
system  as  first  devised.    In  the  early  part  of  the  last  century 


74 


EUEAL   CEEDITS 


complaints  were  made  that  the  low  valuations  fixed  by  the 
management  of  the  landsehaft  on  lands,  the  limitation  of 
loans  to  one-half  of  these  valuations,  slow  and  technical  busi- 
ness methods,  and  the  want  of  regular  amortization,  inter- 
fered with  the  extending  of  reasonable  amounts  of  credit  to 
members  and  discouraged  landowners  from  joining  the  asso- 
ciation, while  the  privilege  which  the  landsehaft  had  of  taking 
possession  of  mortgaged  properties  and  leasing  or  farming^ 
them  until  its  claims  were  satisfied,  prevented  owners  from 
getting  loans  on  second  mortgage  from  other  lenders. 

On  account  of  these  defects  of  the  old  landsehaft  a  new 
association  was  formed  on  June  8,  1835,  under  the  name  of 
the  Eoyal  Credit  Institute  for  Silesia.  Its  heads  were  ap- 
pointed by  the  King,  while  the  ofiBcers  of  the  landsehaft  could 
be  called  upon  to  manage  the  properties  mortgaged  to  it  if 
sequestered  for  arrears.  The  Institute  was  authorized  to  issue 
debentures  styled  "Litera  B,"  even  beyond  two-thirds  the 
value  of  the  land,  and  also  to  take  in  security  properties  al- 
ready mortgaged  to  the  landsehaft.  This  new  concern  was 
dissolved  on  March  4,  1850,  owing  to  the  fact  that  the  old 
landsehaft  had  gradually  made  the  needed  reforms  and  ab- 
sorbed the  busiuess  of  its  rival.  But  inasmuch  as  debentures 
Litera  B  were  in  circulation  in  the  province  the  SHesian 
landsehaft  decided  not  to  adopt  this  name  for  any  subsequent 
issues. 

In  1912  the  amount  of  the  loans  made  by  the  Silesian  land- 
sehaft to  members  during  the  year  was  $850,162,  and  the  total 
amount  of  loans  outstanding  was  $97,919,605,  secured  by 
1,888  mortgaged  estates.  This  was  cover  for  debentures  as. 
follows : 


Old  landsehaft 

debentures $6,153,307 

Litera  A 

debentures 72,517,214 

Litera  C 

debentures    ....  19,249,084 


3  per  cent 
debentures 

3.5  per  cent 
debentures 

4  per  cent 
debentures 


..  .$33,891,869 
...  54,930,371 
. ..    9,097,365 


SILESIAF   LANDSCHAFT:    ITS    FUNDS        75 

The  general  funds  amounted  to  $3,932,763.35,  and  all 
except  $808,740.63  of  cash  and  accounts  received  were  invested 
in  debentures. 

The  amount  paid  into  the  amortization  funds  was  18.58 
per  cent  of  the  debt  for  the  old  landschaft  debentures  and 
7.87  per  cent  for  Litera  A  debentures.  For  Litera  C  deben- 
tures the  amount  -was,  9.37  per  cent  plus  17.06  per  cent  into 
the  special  reserve. 

Duriag  1911  seven  estates  were  sequestered.  One  of  them 
was  released  and  two  were  sold.  In  1912  $39,413.39  of  prin- 
cipal and  $19,833.73  of  interest  were  in  arrears  ia  the  remain- 
ing four  cases.  In  addition,  19  estates  were  $12,396.99  in 
arrears  on  interest  payments. 

The  amount  of  the  loans  made  to  non-members  during  the 
year  was  $875,881,  and  the  total  amount  of  loans  outstanding 
was  $52,409,274,  secured  by  15,996  mortgaged  properties. 
This  was  cover  for  debentures  Litera  D  as  follows: 

3  per  cent  debentures $9,576,560 

3.5  per  cent  debentures 34,098,500 

4  per  cent  debentures 8,734,214 

Mortgages  to  the  number  of  1,372  were  in  force  on  prop- 
erties whose  areas  were  12.35  acres  or  under.  Many  of  the 
mortgaged  properties  were  50  acres  or  over.  The  smallest 
loan  was  $23.81,  and  the  largest  $59,525,  so  it  is  impossible  to 
give  an  average  for  size. 

The  amount  paid  into  the  amortization  fund  for  deben- 
tures Litera  D  was  6.76  per  cent,  and  into  the  reserve  fund 
2.28  per  cent  of  the  debt  of  members. 

During  1911  eight  mortgaged  properties  of  non-mem- 
bers were  sequestered.  Two  of  them  were  released  and  four 
were  sold.  In  1912  $208.90  interest  was  in  arrears  in  the 
remaiaing  two  cases.  In  addition,  343  other  mortgages  were 
$17,137.85  in  arrears  in  interest  payments;  presumably  this 
was  for  sis  months. 

Hence,  the  total  of  the  outstanding  debentures  issued 
against  mortgages  on  lands  of  members  and  non-members 


76  EUEAL   CREDITS 

amounted  to  $150,328,879.    The  quotations  of  the  debentures 
varied  as  follows: 

Old  landschaft  3.5  per  cent  debentures 91.80  to   94.00 

Old  landschaft  4  per  cent  debentures 100.00  "  101.00 

Literse  A,  C,  and  D  3  per  cent  debentures 81.20  "    84.20 

Literae  A,  C,  and  D  3.5  per  cent  debentures. .     90.60  "    93.50 

Literse  A,  C,  and  D  4  per  cent  debentures. . . .     99.65  "  100.85 


CHAPTEE   IX 

THE   OTHEE   GEEMAN  LANDSCHAPTS 

Old  Type  of  Laudschafts  in  Prussia. — State  Aid. — Variations  in  Dif- 
ferent Provinces. — ^Management,  Members  and  Officers. — Credit 
and  Debentures. — Changes  After  Napoleonic  Wars. — ^Privilege 
of  Eeealling  the  Loan. — ^Eeduction  of  Interest. — The  "Conver- 
sion."— Creation  of  a  Sinking  Fund. — ^Posen's  Provincial  Credit 
Association. — The  New  Debentures. — Amortiaation  of  Loans  by 
Annuities. — Extension  of  Landschaft  to  Common  People. — Ee- 
duetion  of  Minimum  for  Credit. — Variations  Among  New  Land- 
schafts. — Central  Landschaft. 

Landschafts  of  the  old  type  were  formed  in  Prussia, 
after  the  origination  of  the  idea  in  Silesia,  in  Kiir  and  Neil- 
mark  on  June  14,  1774;  in  Pomerania  on  March  13,  1781; 
in  West  Prussia  on  April  19,  1787;  in  East  Prussia  on  Feb- 
ruary 16,  1788;  and  at  Cella  in  Liineburg  on  February  16, 
1790. 

All  these  old  landschafts  were  organized  under  the  aus- 
pices of  the  state  and  some  were  generously  subsidized  by  it. 
This  state  intervention  was  almost  a  necessity.  The  title 
and  value  of  land  were  imsettled  by  the  ever  present  fear  of 
war  and  political  disturbances.  Hand  labor  was  hard  to  get. 
The  methods  of  cultivation  were  crude  and  feebly  productive. 
Continual  defaults,  stay  laws,  and  the  delays  or  impossibility 
of  foreclosure  frightened  away  capital  from  agriculture,  and 
farms  were  being  abandoned  because  of  lack  of  funds.  Al- 
though prices  of  food  stuffs  were  inordinately  high,  revenues 
were  small  and  intermittent,  and  the  owners  of  farms  were 
unable  to  pay  regularly  their  taxes  and  war  levies. 

The  trouble  and  the  remedy  appeared  to  be  financial;  so 
the  rest  of  the  afflicted  Prussian  provinces,  inspired  by  the 
successful  example  of  Silesia,  decided  upon  the  creation  of 
public  intermediaries  between  borrowers  and  lenders  to  de- 

77 


78  EUEAL   CREDITS 

termine  questions  relating  to  titles  and  values,  to  issue  bonds 
to  be  used  by  investors  instead  of  direct  mortgage  loans,  and 
finally  to  remove  aU  doubts  about  recovery  by  providing  for 
the  guaranty  of  groups  of  owners  of  valuable  estates,  enforce- 
able by  special  summary  proceedin.gs,  in  place  of  foreclosure 
under  general  laws. 

The  old  landschafts  are  not  all  exactly  alike.  No 
province  but  Silesia  forced  members  to  join  or  imposed  per- 
petual liability  on  their  estates;  nevertheless  all  estates  eli- 
gible for  admission  are  liable  on  the  debentures  of  the  Litera 
A  class  issued  by  the  landschafts  of  Silesia,  Pomerania,  West 
Prussia  and  Bast  Prussia.  In  East  Prussia  the  crown  lands 
and  forests  are  subject  to  the  liability.  In  the  other  prov- 
inces the  liability  runs  only  against  the  estates  actually  mort- 
gaged. This  liability  is  limited  to  contributory  payments 
amounting  to  from  5  to  10  per  cent  of  the  indebtedness  in- 
curred by  the  landschafts  of  Westphalia  and  Saxony  and  by 
one  landschaft  in  Schleswig-Holstein.  The  two  cooperative 
associations  in  Saxony  and  Bavaria  which  extend  real  estate 
credit  according  to  the  landschaft  method  fix  the  liability  at 
$250  per  share,  the  number  of  shares  which  each  borrower  is 
required  to  subscribe  for  being  determined  by  the  amount  of 
his  loan. 

There  were  differences  also  in  structure.  The  land- 
schaft in  Silesia  was  composed  of  nine,  that  in  Pomerania  of 
four,  separate  associations,  each  with  its  own  constitution  and 
funds.  In  West  Prussia  the  landschaft  had  four  departments 
with  separate  directorates,  and  in  Kiir  and  JSTeumark  it  was 
divided  into  four  departments  for  convenience  of  administra- 
tion. All  these  departments  were  subdivided  into  circles.  In 
East  Prussia  the  landschaft  was  divided  for  the  same  purpose 
into  three  departments,  without  any  circles,  and  in  Liineburg 
it  had  only  one  oflBce.  The  structure  of  all  these  old  land- 
schafts still  remains  imchanged,  except  that  East  Prussia  has 
consolidated  her  three  departments  into  one. 

The  scheme  of  management  was  about  the  same  for  all 
the  old  landschafts.  The  members,  although  mutually  liable, 
had  no  voice  in  admitting  members,  in  granting  loans,  or  in 


THE  OTHEE  GEEMAN"  LANDSCHAFTS   79 

any  of  the  business.  Their  participation  in  the  affairs  of  the- 
association  was  confined  to  voting  for  officers  and  delegates  or 
on  measures  relating  to  changes  in  the  constitution,  raising- 
money  for  general  purposes,  or  diverting  funds  from  their 
prescribed  uses.  The  ballots  of  members  were  taken  at  the 
meetings  of  the  lowest  subdivisions.  Over  these  were  the 
regional  boards  and  officers,  or,  if  the  landschaft  was  not  de- 
centralized, the  executive  council  and  central  staff.  Then 
came  a  select  or  permanent  committee  which  represented  the 
general  assembly  when  the  latter  was  not  in  session. 

Members  were  not  allowed  to  sit  in  the  general  assembly. 
This  body,  which  held  the  supreme  control  within  the  land- 
schaft, was  composed  of  delegates  and  officers,  presided  over 
by  a  representative  of  the  Crown.  The  election  of  officer& 
and  amendments  to  the  constitution  and  by-laws  had  to  be 
approved  by  the  Crown.  Supervision  was  exercised  by  a  royal 
commissioner.  The  landschaft  could  make  no  loans  outside 
of  its  designated  territory,  nor  on  any  lands  except  the  estates- 
of  nobles. 

The  officers  in  every  old  landschaft  had  powers  as  public 
officials  in  the  performance  of  their  respective  duties.  Hence- 
their  adjudications  as  to  titles  and  values  and  the  documents, 
and  records  made  by  them  were  incontestable  proof  in  litiga- 
tion between  the  landschaft  and  its  members.  Third  parties- 
could  not  dispute  the  claims  or  liens  of  the  landschaft  or 
interfere  with  or  delay  its  proceedings  to  enforce  recovery. 
Members  of  the  landschaft  were  bound  under  penalty  to  com- 
ply with  all  orders  and  do  any  service  enjoined  upon  them, 
in  respect  to  its  business. 

The  credit  limit,  as  a  rule,  was  fixed  at  one-half  the  ap- 
praised value  of  the  estate.  Members  in  the  Silesian  land"- 
schaft  had  a  right  in  law  to  demand  debentures  up  to  that 
amount  in  exchange  for  their  mortgages.  With  the  other 
landsehafts  the  granting  of  membership  and  credit  was  op- 
tional, but  when  once  accorded,  the  credit  was  intended  to 
continue  until  the  borrower  wished  or  was  able  to  end  it.  No 
provision  was  made  for  the  amortization  of  the  loans.  Th& 
funds  obtained  from  state  subsidies  or  assessments  on  mem- 


80  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

bers  were  not  used  for  reducing  the  loans  or  the  interest  rate. 
They  were  held  with  their  earnings  as  reserves  to  meet  cur- 
rent expenses  or  to  protect  the  landschaft  or  assist  members  in 
emergencies. 

Every  debenture  contained  a  description  of  the  property 
by  which  it  was  primarily  secured,  and  the  holder  had  to 
exhaust  his  remedies  under  the  general  laws  against  the  mort- 
gagor before  calling  upon  the  landschaft  for  payment.  Hence 
the  effect  of  the  landschaft's  signature  to  the  bond  was  simply 
to  give  it  an  easy  negotiability.  To  facilitate  circulation 
coupons  payable  to  bearer  were  issued  in  denominations  from 
$350  down  to  $3.50.  They  were  all  redeemable  at  the  will 
of  the  landschaft,  and  for  a  long  time  also  on  six  months' 
notice  of  the  holder,  a  defect  which  subsequently  jeopardized 
the  entire  system. 

Twenty-eight  years  elapsed  after  the  establishment  of  these 
first  Prussian  landschafts  before  a  new  association  was  suc- 
cessfully launched;  one  formed  for  Schleswig-Holsteia  in 
1811  was  dissolved.  Within  that  period  Napoleon  Bonaparte 
rose,  reigned  and  fell.  Europe  had  been  politically,  and  so- 
cially remolded,  and  the  serfs  in  the  German  states  had  begun 
to  emerge  from  bondage  with  rights  and  needs  which  the  old 
landschafts  were  not  framed  to  recognize. 

The  restriction  of  membership  to  the  owners  of  large 
estates  and  the  employment  of  business  methods  which  were 
antiquated  even  at  the  opening  of  the  century  prevented  these 
institutions  from  meeting  the  requirements  of  the  changing 
conditions.  Other  defects  were  the  lack  of  any  provision  re- 
quiring the  repayment  of  the  principal  of  the  loan,  the  privi- 
lege conceded  to  holders  of  recalling  the  debentures,  and  the 
peculiar  legal  status  which  saved  the  landschafts  from  being 
primarily  responsible  for  obligations  made  and  issued  by 
themselves. 

The  privilege  of  recalling  the  loan,  however,  was  usually 
reserved  by  aU  classes  of  lenders  in  those  days.  Frederick 
the  Great  and  his  advisers  did  not  disturb  this  custom  for 
fear  of  driving  the  investing  public  away  from  the  debentures 
of  the  landschafts,  and  for  the  further  reason  that  they 


THE  OTHEE  GEEMAIsT  LANDSCHAFTS        81 

thought  that  the  subsidies  and  the  imexpended  portion  of  the 
contributions  which  members  paid  for  the  upkeep  of  the 
landschaft  would  eventually  form  a  sufficient  fund  to  meet 
the  usual  number  of  demands  and  protect  its  guaranty.  But 
such  was  not  the  case.  The  demands  were  heavy  whenever 
the  financial  situation  of  the  country  at  large  was  bad,  and 
the  stay  laws  which  Frederick  the  Great's  successor,  Frederick 
William  III,  decreed  for  private  debtors  during  and  after 
the  Napoleonic  wars,  had  to  be  extended  to  the  landschafts. 
Between  1813  and  1814  a  certain  period  of  grace  was  granted 
for  all  the  associations.  For  the  province  of  Pomerania  it 
lasted  imtil  1880.  In  East  Prussia  and  West  Prussia,  which 
had  been  scourged  the  most  by  war,  the  stay  laws  were  re- 
enacted  in  1821,  and  holders  of  debentures  were  enjoined 
against  calling  in  their  loans  until  December  21,  1823.  Fur- 
ther moratoria  were  decreed  and  the  afEairs  of  the  old  asso- 
ciations and  of  the  four  new  ones  which  had  been  formed 
did  not  resume  their  regular  course  until  September  13,  1832. 

During  this  time  debentures  were  redeemed  only  in 
amounts  justified  by  the  available  cash  on  hand.  The  contri- 
butions of  members  of  the  landschafts  were  increased,  but 
many  debenture  holders  had  to  wait  because  the  enemies  had 
confiscated  the  entire  funds  of  some  of  the  associations.  These 
stay  laws  saved  the  landschafts  from  the  only  necessity  they 
ever  faced  of  putting  the  collective  liability  of  members  to 
the  test.  It  cannot  be  conjectured  what  might  have  hap- 
pened if  these  measures  had  not  been  taken. 

It  must  be  remembered,  however,  that  at  intervals  during 
this  period  the  state  itself  was  forced  to  suspend  payments 
and  that  its  credit  was  always  worse  than  that  of  the  land- 
schafts. During  the  Napoleonic  wars  the  debentures  of  the 
Silesian  landschaft  fell  to  84,  then  to  70  and  50,  but  those  of 
the  Prussian  Government  sank  to  20.  In  1839  they  again 
dropped  below  par  when  the  interest  rate  was  arbitrarily  re- 
duced by  royal  decree  from  four  to  three  and  one-half  per  cent, 
but  they  soon  recovered.  The  revolution  of  February,  1848, 
seriously  affected  all  values,  and  during  that  year  the  deben- 
tures  of  the  landschafts   of    Silesia   and   Pomerania  were 


82  EUEAL   CREDITS 

■quoted  at  93,  of  West  Prussia  at  83,  and  of  East  Prussia 
at  96.  But  at  the  same  time  Prussian  government  bonds 
were  selling  at  69,  the  stock  of  the  Bank  of  Prussia  at  63, 
and  the  stock  of  the  government  railroads  from  90  down  to  30. 
Again,  in  1850,  while  the  3.5  per  cent  government  bonds  of 
Prussia  were  at  86.5,  those  of  the  Silesian  landschaft  were 
■quoted  at  90  to  93.75,  those  of  the  landschaft  of  Posen  at  103, 
and  of  the  landschaft  of  Mechlenburg  at  103. 

But  the  bitter  experiences  suffered  by  the  landschafts 
during  the  Napoleonic  wars  and  other  disturbances  showed 
"the  dangerous  possibilities  of  the  error  of  allowing  holders  of 
debentures  the  right  of  demanding  repayment  of  the  principal. 
Its  elimination,  however,  was  accomplished  gradually.  After 
the  country  had  recovered  from  the  damage  wrought  by  the 
wars  and  had  enjoyed  a  few  years  of  peace  and  plenty,  land 
values  steadied  agaia  and  money  began  to  be  f  oimd  in  abun- 
dance for  mortgage  loans  on  reasonable  terms.  The  land- 
schafts were  the  first  to  enjoy  the  effects  of  the  improved 
condition  and  they  decided  to  take  advantage  of  it  for  the 
purpose  of  reducing  the  rate  of  interest  on  their  debentures. 

This  rate  was  four  per  cent,  the  same  prescribed  by  law  in 
the  latter  part  of  the  preceding  century,  and  the  debentures 
were  consequently  selling  at  a  premium  correspondiug  with 
"the  lower  market  rates  for  money,  which  were  between  3  and 
4  per  cent  for  good  investments.  Edicts  permitting  a  reduc- 
tion of  interest  were  published  for  East  Prussia  and  Pome- 
rania  in  1837,  for  West  Prussia  in  1838,  and  for  Silesia  in 
1839.  These  edicts  further  declared  that  debentures  which 
could  be  recalled  by  holders  should  no  longer  be  issued.  The 
correction  of  this  defect,  which  had  jeopardized  their  exist- 
ence from  the  beginning,  was  the  first  innovation  made  in 
"the  old  landschafts. 

The  constitutions  and  by-laws  were  generally  overhauled 
a  few  years  afterward,  and  so  great  was  the  effect  of  the 
various  amendments  that  the  literature  of  the  landschafts 
refers  to  those  times  as  the  epoch  of  the  "conversion."  All 
outstanding  debentures  were  called  in.  The  holders  were 
compelled  to  accept  their  repayment  at  par,  or  their  conver- 


THE  OTHEE  GEEMAN  LANDSCHAFTS        83 

sion  to  314  per  cent  interest  after  1840  for  denominations  of 
$24  or  over,  and  to  3%  per  cent  interest  for  lower  denomina- 
tions. 

As  the  debentures  were  then  quoted  at  a  premium  of 
about  seven  per  cent,  many  complaints  were  raised  against  the 
execution  of  this  drastic  measure,  but  the  conversion  was 
made  with  comparatively  little  trouble.  The  Silesian  land- 
sehaft  did  not  have  to  use  a  loan  which  it  had  taken  the  pre- 
caution to  obtain  from  the  Berlin  bankers.  Out  of  $9,000,- 
000  of  its  debentures  in  circulation,  only  $6,240  were  pre- 
sented for  payment,  and  $120,000  were  converted  as  a  matter 
of  course  upon  the  failure  of  the  holders  to  make  known 
their  wishes.  After  the  reduction  of  the  interest  the  deben- 
tures were  soon  quoted  again  above  par,  and  this  was  the  case 
with  the  other  landschafts  also. 

Inasmuch  as  the  measures  for  converting  the  debentures 
from  four  per  cent  to  a  lower  rate  did  not  provide  at  the  same 
time  for  a  corresponding  reduction  in  the  interest  paid  by 
the  members  on  their  loans,  it  was  apparent  that  unless  some- 
thing were  done  big  funds  would  accumulate  for  which  the 
landschafts  would  have  no  use,  since  the  associations  were  not 
conducted  for  profit.  The  first  proposal  was  to  reduce  the 
interest  on  loans  but  the  idea  of  utilizing  the  difference  to 
create  a  sinking  fund  for  the  retirement  of  the  debentures 
finally  prevailed. 

The  suggesting  cause  of  this  idea  was  imdoubtedly  the 
Provincial  Credit  Association  for  the  Grand  Duchy  of  Posen, 
Prussia.  This  peculiar  institution  was  orgtoized  on  October 
15,  1821,  with  the  object  of  issuing  just  one  series  of  deben- 
tures for  a  group  of  noble  landowners,  and  it  proposed  to  go 
out  of  existence  when  this  bonded  debt  was  paid  off.  Bor- 
rowers contributed  three-fourths  of  one  per  cent  in  addition 
to  their  annual  interest  and  fees,  and  it  was  calculated  that 
the  funds  accumulated  thereby  would  suffice  to  retire  the 
debentures  within  41  years. 

This  association  had  avoided  the  error  of  conceding  to 
debenture  holders  the  privilege  of  recalling  the  principal  on 
notice.     It  reserved  this  right  to  itself  and  exercised  it  by 


84  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

withdrawing- by  lot  each  year  as  many  debentures  as  it  was 
able  to  repay  from  payments  received  from  borrowing  mem- 
bers. Drawings  were  made,  however,  only  when  the  deben- 
tures were  quoted  at  a  premium.  It  is  needless  to  say  that 
when  the  price  was  under  par,  the  association  bought  deben- 
tures in  the  open  market.  A  bonus  of  three  per  cent  was 
given  on  all  debentures  drawn  by  lot.  The  purpose  of  the 
founders  in  creating  a  sinking  fund  by  contributions  of 
members  seems  to  have  been  not  so  much  to  wipe  out  the 
debt  as  to  maintain  the  face  value  of  the  debentures  by  being 
able  always  to  buy  them  back,  and  also  to  compensate  bor- 
rowers whenever  they  happened  to  be  compelled  to  repay  their 
loans  with  debentures  quoted  above  par. 

The  Posen  association  issued  another  series  of  debentures 
in  1840  to  be  redeemed  by  a  1.5  per  cent  annual  contribution 
for  35  years.  Thereafter  it  closed  its  doors  against  further 
applications  for  loans,  and  was  dissolved  in  1877  after  having 
faithfully  met  all  its  obligations,  exactly  as  was  planned  in  its 
original  charter.  This  temporary  institution  was  thus  the 
first  on  the  continent  of  Europe  to  practice  the  extinction  of 
debts  by  compulsory  periodical  payments. 

The  old  landschafts  upon  adopting  the  methods  of  the 
Posen  association  aU  issued  new  series  of  debentures  desig- 
nated by  a  letter  in  the  alphabet  to  distinguish  them  from 
the  old  issues.  These  new  debentures  did  not  contain  the 
names  of  mortgagors  or  descriptions  of  properties  and  were  not 
issued  against  and  secured  by  any  special  mortgages,  as  was 
the  case  with  the  old  bonds.  They  were  secured  by  the  mass 
of  underlying  mortgages  and  the  principal  was  repaid  out  of 
the  amortization  fund.  As  the  association  began  to  collect 
contributions  to  this  fund  from  the  members  and  to  redeem 
debentures  therefrom,  they  assumed,  at  least  in  the  eyes  of  the 
investing  public,  the  primary  and  a  direct  responsibility,  and 
thus  a  second  innovation  was  introduced  into  the  credit  sys- 
tem of  the  old  landschafts.  This  occurred  in  the  different 
landschafts  at  different  dates.  The  issuance  of  debentures  with 
the  mortgaged  estates  described  therein  ceased  in  Silesia  for 
plebeian  borrowers  in  1849,  and  for  noble  estates  in  1872; 


THE   OTHER  GERMAN  LANDSCHAFTS        85 

in  Pomerania  in  1857;  in  Brandenburg  in  1858;  in  West 
Prussia  in  1864;  and  in  East  Prussia  in  1866. 

Since  the  practice  of  making  loans  in  debentures  was 
continued,  the  redemption  of  the  debentures  out  of  the  funds 
paid  by  borrowers  operated  also  for  the  extinction  of  their 
debts,  and  brought  about  the  third  and  greatest  innovation  in 
the  old  landschafts,  the  amortization  of  the  loans  by  an- 
nuities. 

The  landschafts  do  not  all  use  exactly  the  same  method  of 
amortization.  The  differences  lie  mainly  in  the  amount  of 
the  annual  contribution  and  the  period  during  which  it  must 
be  paid,  the  way  the  sinking  fund  thus  created  is  kept,  and 
the  rights  of  the  members  therein.  The  methods,  however, 
are  so  much  alike  as  all  to  fall  within  the  class  known  as  the 
"landschaf t  plan,"  to  distinguish  them  from  the  entirely  dif- 
ferent methods  used  by  other  land-credit  institutions. 

Generally  speaking,  a  borrower  in  a  landschaft  pays  what 
is  called  an  annuity  in  half-yearly  instalments,  which  remains 
the  same  as  long  as  he  is  indebted  to  the  association.  This 
annuity  is  divided  into  three  portions.  The  first  portion  is 
used  for  paying  the  interest  on  the  debentures  by  which  the 
money  for  making  the  loan  was  obtained;  the  second  is  set 
aside  for  the  cost  of  business;  and  the  third  portion,  usually 
one-fourth  or  one-half  of  one  per  cent,  is  placed  in  the  sinking 
fund,  together  with  all  voluntary  payments  which  the  bor- 
rower may  have  made  in  advance  on  his  loan.  This  fund  is 
invested  in  debentures  redeemed  or  purchased  on  the  bourse. 
The  borrower  is  given  a  share  in  this  sinking  fund  propor- 
tioned to  the  amount  of  his  loan,  and  when  his  credits  and  his 
portion  of  the  profits  equal  his  loan,  it  is  considered  paid  and 
his  mortgage  is  annulled  and  released  of  record. 

Although  no  provision  is  made  for  the  extinction  of  the 
loan  at  the  end  of  a  fixed  period,  a  borrower  in  a  landschaft 
knows  that  if  he  faithfully  fulfills  his  engagements,  that 
portion  of  his  annuity  which  represents  payments  on  the  prin- 
cipal will  be  carefully  invested  to  his  account  at  compound 
interest,  and  will  gradually  relieve  his  property  from  debt  in 
a  cheaper  and  more  convenient  way  than  by  any  other  system. 


86  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  release  also  wiU  come  sooner  than  in  a  company  which 
has  to  pay  dividends  to  stockholders,  because  a  borrower  in 
a  landsehaft,  besides  receiving  aU  the  profits  of  his  money 
safely  invested,  enjoys  his  share  in  the  savings  and  gains  of 
an  association  whose  chief  objects  are  to  eliminate  expenses 
and  commissions  and  to  extend  credit  to  its  members  on  the 
lowest  and  easiest  terms. 

The  changes  in  the  form  and  effect  of  the  debenture  and 
the  introduction  of  the  amortization  idea  were  followed  by 
another  reform  which  extended  the  benefits  of  the  landsehaft 
to  practically  all  landed  farmers,  noble  and  plebeian.  But 
this  fourth  innovation  was  agitated  and  incepted  before  any 
of  the  others.  In  1807  the  King  of  Prussia  decreed  that  the 
common  people  should  have  the  right  to  own  manorial  estates, 
which  up  to  that  time  could  be  owned  only  by  the  nobility. 
The  landsehaft  of  East  Prussia  was  the  first  to  amend  its 
charter  and  by-laws  to  conform  with  the  spirit  of  this  decree. 
The  others  made  similar  amendments.  This,  however,  was 
only  a  short  step  forward,  because  the  estates  were  large  and 
the  high  figure  prescribed  in  the  charters  of  the  landschafts 
as  the  minimum  value  for  membership  was  not  reduced.  The 
small  holder  was  still  excluded.  Hence  about  the  middle  of 
the  century,  after  the  multitudes  of  serfs  had  been  completely 
freed  from  menial  servitude  and  given  full  rights  of  citizen- 
ship, it  became  evident  that  the  minimum  for  credit  must  be 
reduced  if  the  landschafts  were  to  render  to  agriculture  ser- 
vices commensurate  with  its  needs.  This  was  the  fifth  and 
last  innovation. 

The  desired  reforms  were  accomplished  in  various  ways. 
The  East  Prussian  landsehaft  lowered  the  minimum  value  of 
farm  required  for  membership  to  500  marks.  The  other  old 
landschafts  preserved  in  the  main  their  aristocratic  character, 
but  the  SUesian  institution  opened  a  bureau  in  1849  for 
making  loans  on  small  rural  holdings ;  while  in  West  Prussia 
in  1861,  in  Kiir  and  Neumark  in  1869,  and  in  Pomerania  in 
1871,  subsidiary  associations  to  make  loans  on  farm  lands 
yielding  an  annual  revenue  as  low  as  $24  were  formed  by  the 
landschafts  and  operated  under  their  management.     More- 


THE  OTHEE  GEEMAN"  LANDSCHAFTS        87 

over,  new  landschafts  entirely  separate  and  distinct  from  the 
old  institutions  were  organized  in  Prussia  and  in  nearly 
all  the  other  German  states. 

Although  constructed  along  the  same  general  lines,  uni- 
formity of  tjrpe  does  not  appear  among  the  new  landschafts, 
while  they  difier  in  important  respects  from  the  old  land- 
schafts. Noble  lineage  and  seignorial  tenure  have  been  dis- 
carded as  qualifications  for  membership.  Every  deserving 
farmer  resident  within  the  area  of  operation  may  join  the 
association  if  he  owns  a  piece  of  agriciiltural  land  of  the  size 
or  value  prescribed  in  the  by-laws,  but  no  one  is  obliged  to 
become  a  member.  Liability  for  the  obligations  of  the  asso- 
ciation runs  only  against  those  who  have  borrowed.  The 
extent  of  this  liability  varies.  In  some  associations  it  covers 
all  the  real  estate  which  members  may  possess;  in  others  it 
extends  only  to  the  mortgaged  property,  no  other  properties 
owned  by  the  members  being  subject  to  it.  The  mutual  lia- 
bility also  is  frequently  limited  to  a  percentage  of  the  loans 
of  the  members.  Six  of  the  new  landschafts  have  done  away 
with  mutual  liability  altogether.  Each  member  is  held  to 
pay  only  his  own  loan  and  is  not  bound  to  stand  as  guaranty 
for  those  of  the  others.  The  losses  in  these  associations  are 
met  out  of  a  guaranty  fund  created  by  extra  contributions  or 
entrance  fees  paid  by  their  members.  In  all  the  new  asso- 
ciations the  farmer  must  sign  when  his  loan  is  made  a  mem- 
bership agreement  binding  him  to  obey  the  rules  and  regu- 
lations of  the  association.  He  ceases  to  be  a  member  upon 
repayment  of  his  loan  but  his  liability  continues  for  a  certain 
length  of  time  thereafter. 

Two  of  the  new  institutions  are  similar  to  the  cooperative 
associations  for  personal  credit  which  will  be  described  later. 
They  impose  unlimited  liability  on  their  members,  but  this  lia- 
bility is  protected  by  the  capital  stock  divided  into  shares  to 
which  members  must  subscribe  upon  joining.  The  capital 
stock  is  variable  in  each  association  and  shares  are  issued  only 
as  borrowers  are  admitted  to  membership.  They  may  be  paid 
in  full  at  the  time  of  subscription  or  in  successive  instal- 
ments.   Upon  withdrawal  from  the  association,  the  amount 


88  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

of  his  shares  is  returned  to  the  retiring  member  upon  sur- 
render of  the  stock  certificates.  These  are  adaptations  of  the 
building  and  loan  associations  in  the  United  States. 

The  debentures  of  the  new  as  well  as  the  old  landschafts 
are  all  of  the  new  style,  that  is,  they  do  not  contain  the  name 
of  any  specially  described  property  but  are  worded  to  show 
that  they  rest  upon  reserves  and  a  mass  of  underlying  mort- 
gages. The  methods  of  issuance  are  not  identical.  Most  of 
the  associations  deliver  the  debentures  to  the  borrowers,  but 
some  make  the  loans  in  cash,  raising  the  money  therefor  by 
selliag  the  debentures  on  the  bourse.  If  they  are  sold  below 
par,  the  association  charges  the  borrower  a  little  higher  in- 
terest rate  in  order  to  create  a  fund  to  amortize  the  difference 
between  the  amount  of  the  loan  and  the  sum  actually  re- 
ceived. Some  of  the  associations,  in  lieu  of  specifying  the 
rate  of  interest  on  the  loans  in  advance,  fix  only  the  size  of 
the  annuity,  generally  about  5  per  cent.  The  association  then 
disposes  of  the  debentures  on  the  best  possible  terms,  charges 
the  borrower  the  rate  of  interest  computed  for  the  transaction, 
and  deposits  the  difference  between  that  and  the  annuity  in 
the  sinking  fund.  In  this  case  the  borrower  does  not  Imow 
in  advance  what  will  be  the  exact  rate  of  interest  he  will  be 
required  to  pay  or  what  portion  of  his  annual  dues  will  be 
used  for  amortization.  Although  this  uncertain  method  could 
not  be  employed  by  a  company  which  has  to  distribute  its 
gains  in  dividends,  it  occasions  no  inconvenience  to  the  land- 
schaft  whose  sole  purpose  is  the  collective  good  of  its  members. 

The  need  or  advantage  of  having  a  central  organization 
for  standardizing  their  business  methods  and  strengthening 
their  credit  by  mutual  assistance  became  apparent  as  soon  as 
the  landschafts  had  spread  over  Germany.  Between  1870 
and  1875  the  market  price  of  the  debentures  of  several  of 
the  associations  was  low  and  unstable.  Inasmuch  as  their 
business  methods  were  practically  the  same,  and  the  guaran- 
ties offered  were  as  good  as  those  of  others  whose  debentures 
were  selling  at  a  satisfactory  figure,  it  was  evident  that  the 
difference  was  due  to  distance  from  the  money  centers  and 


THE  OTHEE  GEEMAN"  LANDSCHAFTS   89 

adverse  local  conditions.  Although  such  local  troubles  of  a 
serious  nature  have  been  infrequent  with  the  landschafts, 
they  are  nevertheless  inevitably  recurrent,  and  render  an  iso- 
lated institution,  depending  on  the  financial  resources  of  the 
affected  area,  absolutely  helpless  to  afford  the  needed  relief. 

The  efforts  to  bring  a  central  organization  into  existence 
have  been  only  partially  successful.  Prussia  alone  has  such 
an  institution.  In  devising  plans  for  its  formation  Prussia 
not  only  opened  up  the  financial  channels  which  aU  converge 
at  Berlin,  but  utilized  the  principle  of  cooperation,  and  en- 
couraged the  landschafts  themselves  to  unite  into  a  large 
association  with  power  to  issue  debentures  upon  their  com- 
bined guaranty,  and  thus  to  create  a  security  so  safe  and 
sound  that  it  woxild  have  all  Europe  for  its  market.  This 
idea  was  the  outcome  of  the  report  of  an  investigating  com- 
mittee appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  to  make 
recommendations  for  the  improvement  of  farm-credit  facili- 
ties. The  committee  did  not  submit  any  definite  proposal  for 
a  central  institution,  but  it  voted  in  favor  of  centralization  as 
a  means  of  effecting  the  needed  improvement,  and  a  few 
years  later  the  landschafts  of  the  eastern  provinces  of  Prussia 
took  the  necessary  steps  to  bring  about  its  realization. 

The  Central  Landschaft  of  Prussia  was  organized  in 
1873.  Eight  landschafts  and  one  communal  land-credit  in- 
stitution joined,  of  which  all  but  one  stiU  adhere.  The 
others  declined  to  join  for  fear  of  losing  their  independence, 
and  because  they  thought  that  the  less  flourishing  associa- 
tions would  profit  to  the  disadvantage  of  the  more  prosperous 
ones.  There  has  been  no  need  for  others  to  join,  because  the 
debentures  of  each  landschaft  have  found  such  a  ready  sale 
within  its  own  province  that  it  has  not  been  forced  to  seek  out- 
side assistance.  Hence  the  business  of  the  central  association 
has  not  grown  as  much  as  was  expected,  but  the  fact  that  it 
exists  and  is  available  in  times  of  distress  has  undoubtedly 
strengthened  public  confidence  in  the  debentures  of  the  entire 
Prussian  landschaft  system. 

The  organization  of  this  central  association  is  simple  and 
allows  the  adhering  members  the  fullest  liberty  of  action 


90  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

consistent  with  safety.  It  is  not  operated  for  profit.  Al- 
though possessed  of  the  powers  of  a  corporation,  it  has  no 
capital  stock  and  pays  no  dividends.  Its  members  must  be 
other  associations  or  companies  which  lend  on  farm  mort- 
gages.   All  such  concerns  in  Prussia  are  eligible  to  join. 

Its  administration,  under  the  supervision  of  the  provin- 
cial Minister  of  the  Interior,  is  conducted  simply  by  a  man- 
aging board  composed  of  the  president  of  each  of  the  adhering 
associations.  The  president  of  the  landschaft  or  the  Rit- 
terschaft  of  Kiir  and  Neumark  is  legally  the  president  of  the 
central  board,  for  the  reason  perhaps  that  the  headquarters  of 
both  are  in  Berlin.  It  convenes  whenever  necessary  and  at 
least  once  a  year.  In  the  intervals  the  ordinary  business 
transactions  are  carried  on  by  a  stafE  of  employees. 

Loans  may  be  granted  up  to  two-thirds  the  appraised 
value  of  a  farm,  if  permitted  by  the  rules  of  the  landschaft 
of  the  territory  in  which  it  lies.  They  are  made  either  in 
debentures  or  cash  as  the  central  association  may  decide. 
They  are  usually  made  in  debentures  if  ak)ve  par,  the  pre- 
mium being  placed  in  the  reserve  fund ;  if  the  debentures  are 
below  par,  the  borrower  will  be  given  a  cash  loan  for  the  dif- 
ference. An  extra  one-half  of  one  per  cent  is  required  on  the 
cash  loan  until  it  is  paid.  Otherwise,  the  appraisals  and 
contributions  for  the  gradual  extinction  of  the  debenture 
debt  are  made  according  to  the  rules  of  the  landschaft  to 
which  the  borrower  belongs. 

The  debentures  of  the  central  association  are  issued  in 
denominations  of  $2,400,  $1,200,  $720,  $360,  $144,  $120,  $72, 
$48,  $36  and  $24,  of  four  per  cent,  three  and  one-half  per  cent 
and  three  per  cent,  with  ten  interest  coupons  attached  and  a 
talon  entitling  the  holder  to  a  fresh  series  of  ten  coupons; 
other  denominations  are  allowed.  The  debentures  are  printed 
in  several  languages.  When  a  loan  is  paid  debentures  to  a 
corresponding  amount  must  be  retired;  hence  no  debentures 
are  ever  in  circulation  in  excess  of  the  loans.  No  limit  is 
prescribed  for  the  total  of  business  that  may  be  done. 

The  central  association  does  not  advance  money  to  the 
other  landschafts  or  companies,  nor  does  it  use  them  as  its 


THE   OTHEE  GEEMAN  LANDSCHAFTS        91 

agents  or  in  any  other  way  for  the  disposal  of  its  debentures. 
It  carries  on  business  like  an  ordinary  landschaft.  Its  pur- 
pose is  simply  to  create  a  security  that  will  enable  members 
of  its  adhering  institutions  to  obtain  credit  at  a  fair  figure 
during  hard  times. 

If  a  farmer  finds  that  the  debentures  of  the  local  land- 
schaft of  which  he  is  a  member  are  not  selling  at  a  good  price, 
he  has  the  privilege  of  requesting  that  his  loan  be  made  in 
debentures  of  the  central  landschaft.  His  land  is  appraised 
by  and  mortgaged  to  his  local  landschaft,  which  issues  its 
own  debentures  in  the  ordinary  way.  Its  president  (who  is 
also  a  member  of  the  central  board)  delivers  these  papers 
with  the  other  necessary  documents  to  the  central  associa- 
tion, which  exchanges  them  for  central  debentures.  Thus  by 
this  pledge  the  farmer  gets  a.  bond  backed  by  the  collective 
liability  of  the  thousands  of  other  farmers  belonging  to  the 
landschafts  adhering  to  the  central  association,  and  very  nat- 
urally the  rate  of  interest  is  as  low  as  it  is  possible  to  obtain 
on  borrowed  money  at  that  time. 

The  central  landschaft  has  no  large  funds  besides  the  sink- 
ing fund  accumulated  from  the  contributions  made  for  the 
retirement  of  its  debentures,  and  it  does  not  have  muel^need 
of  any.  The  few  gains  it  makes  from  premiums  and  un- 
claimed debentures  or  coupons  are  safely  invested  in  land- 
schaft debentures  or  government  bonds  and  form  a  reserve; 
the  profits  thereon  revert  to  the  borrowers  if  the  fund  becomes 
needlessly  large.  The  association  is  run  at  comparatively  lit- 
tle expense,  lio  salaries  are  paid  except  for  clerical  services. 
The  iuterest  on  its  loans  is  collected  by  the  various  land- 
schafts, and  they  are  obligated  to  make  immediate  payment 
out  of  their  own  funds  in  case  of  default  of  any  of  the  bor- 
rowers. 


CHAPTER  X 

GERMAN    PUBLIC    LAND-CREDIT    INSTITUTIONS 

Land-credit  Institutions  Other  Than  Landsehafts. — ^Necessity  for 
Their  Creation. — Three  Classes. — ^Land-credit  Banks. — Original 
Purpose  to  Commute  Feudal  Servitudes. — ^Present  Purpose  to 
Supply  Cheap  Money  on  Land  Security. — Operation. — ^Land-im- 
provement Annuity  Banks. — ^Purpose  to  Finance  Land-improve- 
ment Projects. — Operation. — Settlement  Commission. — ^Purpose  to 
Create  Small  Homesteads. — History. — Operation. — State  Invalid- 
ity and  Old-age  Insurance  Institutions. 

The  landsehafts  are  usually  reckoned  among  public 
credit  institutions;  but  while  the  old  associations  which  are 
governed  by  crown  appointees  have  a  public  character,  some 
of  the  new  ones  are  purely  private  associations.  As  they 
now  stand,  they  cannot  all  be  grouped  in  one  category. 

The  public  land-credit  institutions  properly  so  called  in 
Germany  were  created  to  supply  the  deficiencies  in  the  land- 
sehafts, and  to  finance  operations  which  they  were  not  author- 
ized to  assist.  The  landsehafts,  like  their  aristocratic  mem- 
bers, adjusted  themselves  with  bad  grace  to  the  march  of 
events.  On  the  breaking  up  of  feudalism  they  gave  very 
little  help  to  the  plebeian  landovmers  and  practically  none  at 
all  to  the  liberated  serfs.  In  1887  the  German  ministry  of 
agriculture  reported  that  the  landsehafts  did  not  reach  the 
one-team  farmer,  that  is,  the  farmer  of  18  to  34  or  even  61 
acres.  In  1891  the  French  writer  Louis  Durand  made  a  simi- 
lar statement.  In  1895  Sir  Frederick  A.  Nicholson,  after  an 
exhaustive  investigation  in  Germany,  declared  that  they  had 
failed  to  assist  the  majority  of  small  farmers.  Hence  the 
service  which  the  landsehafts  are  now  doing  this  class  began 
within  the  last  15  or  20  years. 

Again,  when  lands  had  to  be  reclaimed  and  the  area  of 

92 


PUBLIC  LAND-CEEDIT  INSTITUTIONS        93 

productivity  enlarged  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  rapidly  grow- 
ing population,  the  landschafts  were  of  no  service,  since  they 
could  give  credit  only  on  lands  that  were  already  improved  or 
capable  of  yielding  an  immediate  revenue.  Private  capital 
was  not  available  for  any  of  these  objects  because  lenders 
during  that  period  found  safer  and  higher  profits  for  their 
money  in  enterprises  of  industry  and  commerce  in  the  cities. 
The  state,  therefore,  intervened  from  a  national  necessity, 
and  in  organizing  land  credit  for  the  general  purposes  of  agri- 
culture, granted  a  greater  degree  of  assistance  than  was  avail- 
able to  the  nobility  in  the  landschafts.  With  two  exceptions 
all  existing  land-credit  institutions  whose  organization  dates 
back  to  1863  were  aided  by  the  state,  while  many  others 
of  later  origin  were  brought  into  existence  in  the  same 
way. 

Exclusive  of  the  landschafts,  there  are  now  three  classes 
of  public  land-credit  institutions  in  Germany.  Institutions 
of  the  first  class  aim  to  obtain  cheap  money  for  all  citizens 
who  have  good  lands  to  ofiEer  as  security ;  those  of  the  second 
class  finance  land  improvement  projects;  and  those  of  the 
third  class  have  for  object  the  creation  of  homesteads  for 
small  holders. 

All  these  public  concerns  are  non-profit-making.  They 
grant  long-term  reducible  mortgage  loans  and  issue  deben- 
tures to  raise  the  money  needed  for  carrying  on  their  opera- 
tions. These  debentures  have  no  fixed  maturity,  are  drawn 
in  small  denominations  payable  to  bearer,  and  are  redeemable 
at  the  will  of  the  makers  out  of  the  annuities  received  from 
the  borrowers.  Their  final  security  is  the  guaranty  of  the 
Government,  and  they  may  be  used  as  investments  for  funds 
of  savings  banks,  insurance  companies,  and  aU  kinds  of  trus- 
tees. The  concerns  are  exempt  from  stamp  taxes  and  regis- 
tration fees,  enjoy  free  services  of  state  oflBcials,  and  possess 
other  special  privileges  in  the  way  of  summary  proceedings 
to  enforce  the  collection  of  their  claims.  They  are  so  widely 
distributed  that  almost  every  German  farmer  is  able  to  dis- 
pose of  his  mortgage  at  a  government  agency  and  obtain  a 
loan  up  to  one-half  or  two-thirds  the  value  of  his  land 


94  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

without  eommissions  or  incidental  expenses  and  at  the  lowest 
interest  rate. 

In  the  first  class  are  the  land-credit  banks  established  for 
a  whole  state,  province,  or  district  within  a  province.  These 
now  number  16.  The  first  provincial  land-credit  bank  with  a 
state  guaranty  in  Germany  was  the  Herzogliche  Leichkasse 
iu  Brunswick,  founded  in  1765 ;  the  first  bank  of  that  nature 
with  a  communal  guaranty  was  founded  in  Cassel  in  1832; 
the  first  bank  with  a  provincial  guaranty  is  the  Hanoverian 
Land-credit  Institute,  founded  in  1840;  the  latest  is  the  one 
founded  in  1903  in  the  Grand  Duchy  of  Hesse.  The  larger 
number  are  joint-stock  concerns,  the  shares  of  which  are  held 
by  the  provinces,  communes,  and  public  savings  banks  of  their 
localities.  They  are  managed  by  committees  appointed  by 
stockholders  and  are  under  state  control. 

The  original  purpose  of  these  banks  was  the  lending  of 
money  to  proprietors  to  enable  them  to  commute  into  mort- 
gage loans  the  feudal  servitudes  which  burdened  their  lands. 
After  this  service  was  no  longer  required,  the  banks  took  up 
the  general  business  of  granting  credit  to  communes  and  on 
mortgage  to  individuals  for  any  object.  Three  of  the  banks 
lend  on  lands  situated  anywhere  in  the  Empire;  the  rest 
confine  their  operations  to  their  own  states.  They  aUhave 
been  serviceable,  especially  to  owners  of  small  or  medium- 
sized  parcels,  but  only  the  bank  in  Hanover  restricts  its  busi- 
ness to  farm  loans.  These  banks,  however,  do  not  conform 
to  the  pure  type  of  land-credit  institution,  because  they  accept 
deposits,  make  personal  loans,  and  accommodate  churches, 
cooperative  societies,  and  public  corporations  with  or  without 
mortgages.  One  of  them  is  authorized  to  issue  notes,  while 
others  have  extensive  banking  powers.  Moreover  they  differ 
so  much  one  from  another  in  function  and  organization  that 
they  can  be  denominated  as  belonging  to  the  same  class  only 
because  of  their  common  connection  with  the  state. 

The  loans  of  the  public  land-credit  banks  are  usually  made 
in  cash,  not  debentures,  but  the  mortgage  and  communal  loans 
may  be  repaid  in  debentures  by  the  borrowers.  The  value  of 
land  is  generally  determiued  by  taking  the  net  revenue  as 


PUBLIC  LAND-CREDIT  INSTITUTIONS        95 

fixed  for  public  taxes  and  multiplying  it  by  25  or  some  such 
figure,  and  then  fixing  two-thirds  of  the  result  as  the  maxi- 
mum for  a  loan.  Six  of  the  banks  lend  sums  as  small  as  $75 ; 
the  minimum  loan  of  another  is  $10.50.  The  rate  of  interest 
ranges  from  three  and  five-tenths  to  four  per  cent  (or  the  rate 
on  the  debentures),  to  which  is  added  one-fourth  to  one-half 
of  one  per  cent  for  cost  of  business,  and  one-half  to  three- 
fourths  of  one  per  cent  for  amortization,  thus  making  the 
largest  annuity  five  and  seventy-five  hundredths  per  cent. 

All  gains  of  the  banks  are  used  for  reducing  the  loans  if 
not  devoted  to  some  public  purpose.  Public  officials  pass 
upon  the  applications  for  loans,  and  collect  the  interest  and 
other  payments.  A  sympathetic  attitude  is  assumed  toward 
delinquents.  Eenewals  and  extensions  are  readily  granted 
upon  good  cause  shown,  while  pajTnents  in  advance  are  always 
allowed.  The  retirement  of  the  debentures  is  effected  by 
drawing  lots,  if  they  are  quoted  above  par :  otherwise  they  are 
obtained  by  purchase  on  the  bourse.  The  largest  denomina- 
tion is  $7,500  and  smallest  $50.  In  1909  the  average  interest 
rate  on  debentures  in  circulation  was  between  3.52  and  3.66 
per  cent. 

The  second  class  of  state-aided  institutions  comprises 
five  land-improvement  annuity  banks  in  Prussia,  one  similar 
institution  in  each  of  four  other  German  provinces,  and  eleven 
provincial-aid  banks.  The  latter  are  simply  governmental 
departments.  They  are  not  important  sources  of  credit  for 
individual  landowners.  With  two  exceptions  they  make 
loans  principally  to  municipalities,  public  corporations  and 
cooperative  societies.  As  yet  their  operations  are  insignifi- 
cant. 

The  land-improvement  annuity  banks  are  organized  for 
the  administration  of  appropriations  from  public  funds,  and 
are  empowered  also  to  issue  guaranteed  debentures  to  raise 
any  other  money  required  for  their  operations.  The  Prussian 
law  of  1879  illustrates  the  objects  of  all  the  institutions.  It 
authorizes  the  creation  of  these  banks  by  one  or  more  com- 
munal districts,  for  the  purpose  of  granting  loans  for  im- 
proving or  reclaiming  agricultural  lands  by  drainage  or  irri- 


96  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

gation,  for  planting  forests,  building  roads,  diking  rivers, 
and  opening  up  and  maintaining  watercourses. 

Each  bank  is  managed  by  a  directorate  of  a  semi-public 
character  and  is  supervised  by  a  bureau  or  department  of  the 
Government.  A  plan  of  the  proposed  project,  with  an  esti- 
mate of  the  cost,  the  time  required  for  completion,  and  the 
probable  value  that  will  be  added  to  the  land,  must  accom- 
pany every  application  for  a  loan.  Agricultural  experts  are 
always  appointed  on  the  commission  which  investigates  this 
application,  and  an  appeal  lies  in  all  cases  from  the  directorate 
to  the  Government. 

Loans  are  allowed  up  to  a  certain  multiple  of  the  net  reve- 
nue of  the  land  as  calculated  for  taxes.  The  limit  in  Prussia 
is  one-half  the  value,  unless  the  increase  from  the  improve- 
ment is  taken  into  consideration,  when  three-fourths  of  the 
value  may  be  allowed.  The  loans  may  be  made  in  cash  or 
with  debentures.  The  debentures  issued  by  each  bank  cannot 
exceed  in  amount  the  loans  granted,  and  both  must  bear  the 
same  interest  rate.  If  a  bank  makes  its  loans  in  cash,  it  may 
issue  and  sell  a  corresponding  number  of  debentures. 

The  rate  of  interest  charged  borrowers  must  not  exceed 
4.5  per  cent;  to  this  must  be  added  at  least  one-half  of  one 
per  cent  for  the  sinking  fund,  with  a  commission  not  to  exceed 
one-fifth  of  one  per  cent  for  the  cost  of  business.  On  loans 
for  drainage  works,  four  per  cent  per  year  may  be  required 
for  amortization.  But  the  annuities  must  be  so  calculated 
that  enough  will  be  left  out  of  the  annual  return  of  the  land 
for  the  living  expenses  of  the  ovmer.  The  money  lent  is 
usually  advanced  by  instalment  upon  favorable  report  of 
progress  made  in  the  work;  thus  the  loan  is  always  used  for 
the  purpose  for  which  it  was  granted. 

A  mortgage  or  a  first  lien  of  some  other  kind  must  be  given 
on  farm  or  forest  lands  as  security  for  each  loan.  A  special 
proceeding  is  allowed  for  establishing  a  loan  used  for  making 
improvements  as  a  first  lien  on  the  land,  regardless  of  prior 
encumbrances  of  third  parties. 

Loans  may  be  made  to  individuals,  to  groups  of  persons, 
and  to  incorporated  bodies  and  cooperative  societies.      The 


PUBLIC  LAND-CEEDIT  INSTITUTIONS        97 

debentures  are  drawn  in  denominations  of  $50  down  to  $2, 
and  bear  ten  4.5  per  cent  interest  coupons  and  a  certificate  en- 
titling the  holder  to  another  set  of  coupons.  Every  six  months 
as  many  debentures  are  retired  as  may  be  redeemed  out  of 
the  annuities  received  from  the  borrowers  during  that  period. 

All  profits  must  be  put  into  the  reserve  until  it  equals 
five  per  cent  of  the  outstanding  debentures.  Any  excess  not 
needed  for  expenses  is  turned  over  to  the  official  bodies  which 
siand  responsible  for  the  debentures. 

The  last  of  the  three  classes  of  state-aided  institutions 
consists  of  a  settlement  commission,  eight  general  commis- 
sions, and  seven  rent  charge  banks,  all  in  Prussia.  The  set- 
tlement commission  has  received  $150,000,000  from  the  state. 
Its  object  is  to  colonize  German  farmers  among  the  Poles  in 
West  Prussia  and  Posen,  and  it  carries  on  this  work  through 
six  hundred  officers. 

The  general  commissions  are  similar  organizations  estab- 
lished by  the  state  for  creating  small  holdings.  In  further- 
ance of  this  object  they  have  been  given  judicial  powers  to 
decide  certain  claims  and  rights  to  properties,  and  they  are 
authorized  to  acquire  and  reforest  moors  and  waste  lands, 
consolidate  separate  tracts  belonging  to  the  same  person,  carry 
out  land-improvement  projects,  and  form  cooperative  societies 
for  irrigation  and  drainage  enterprises.  The  settlement  com- 
mission transacts  its  own  affairs,  but  the  general  commissions 
use  the  rent  charge  banks  as  their  financial  agents. 

The  rent  charge  banks  were  originally  devised  for  assist- 
ing the  emancipated  serfs  to  obtain  clear  titles  to  the  lands 
they  occupied,  and  most  of  them  went  out  of  existence,  as  it 
was  intended  they  should,  when  that  object  was  accomplished. 
The  law  of  1807  which  put  an  end  to  villeinage  and  enabled 
these  agricultural  slaves  for  the  first  time  to  go  and  come 
at  will  and  buy  and  sell  as  free  citizens,  did  not  remove  the 
ancient  restrictions  regarding  the  conveyance  of  land  nor 
change  the  rights  possessed  by  the  noble  landlords  to  a  portion 
of  the  crops  and  certain  field  services  from  tenants  who  cared 
to  remain.  Hence  another  law  was  enacted  in  1811  which 
gave  the  title  to  the  hereditary  tenants.     The  landlord's 


98  EUEAL   CREDITS 

claims  were  commuted  to  one-third  the  income  of  the  land 
and  the  new  owners  were  allowed  to  make  mortgages  to  that 
extent. 

This  commutation  was  made  in  several  ways.  If  the 
land  was  more  than  35  acres  in  area,  one-third  of  it  was  left 
to  the  landlord  and  the  other  two-thirds  was  given  to  the 
tenant  outright:  if  under  that  area,  it  was  subjected  to  a 
perpetual  corn  or  money  rent.  Later  in  1811  these  rent 
charges  were  made  redeemable  by  a  capital  payment,  and 
transfers  were  permitted  so  that  the  land  might  pass  into 
the  hands  of  those  best  fitted  to  cultivate  it.  This  legisla- 
tion regarding  commutation  and  redemption  of  lands  from 
feudal  charges  was  mostly  of  a  permissive  sort,  and  since  the 
farmers  had  neither  money  nor  credit,  it  had  little  effect  in 
bringing  about  the  objects  dosired.  Furthermore,  it  was  lim- 
ited by  the  laws  of  1816  to  a  certain  class  of  tenants,  and  later 
on  by  the  size  of  the  farm,  none  under  18  acres  being  consid- 
ered. 

In  1845,  however,  all  peasant  farms,  no  matter  how 
small,  were  brought  within  its  scope,  the  rent  charges  were 
declared  commutable  at  25  years'  purchase,  and  societies 
were  formed  for  creating  sinking  funds  to  amortize  the  debt. 
Then,  after  the  social  disturbances  of  1848,  came  the  law  of 
March  2,  1850,  which  did  away  with  certain  manorial  rights 
without  compensation,  ordered  the  commutation  of  other 
feudal  rights  and  services  into  fixed  money  rents,  arbitrarily 
established  the  value  of  the  land  at  18  times  the  annual  rent 
for  a  cash  payment  or  at  20  times  for  a  deferred  payment, 
and  obliged  the  nobles  to  accept  that  payment  either  in  lump 
or  in  annuities  calculated  to  extinguish  the  capital  within  41 
to  56  years.  Inasmuch  as  this  was  a  forcible  measure  politi- 
cally inspired  and  urged  by  a  national  necessity,  the  Govern- 
ment naturally  created  the  machinery  to  carry  it  into  effect. 
The  rent  charge  banks  were  the  result. 

These  banks  made  no  loans.  They  had  nothing  to  do  with 
appraising  property  or  determining  the  extent  of  credit.  A 
general  commission  or  government  land  office  commuted  and 
settled  the  claim,  which  was  thereupon  examined  by  a  special 


PUBLIC  LAISTD-CEEDIT  INSTITUTIONS        99 

commissioner,  and  then,  if  the  appellate  commission  did  not 
disturb  the  decision,  the  rent  charge  bank  was  ordered  to 
issue  debentures  up  to  30  times  the  amount  of  the  award. 
It  delivered  these  debentures  to  the  peasant,  debiting  him 
with  their  value  on  the  security  of  his  land;  the  credit  so 
accorded  formed  a  first  lien  and  followed  the  land  and  not 
the  person.  The  interest  coupons  were  legal  tender  at  gov- 
ernment ofBces.  Annuities  were  collected  by  the  public  tax 
gatherers.  The  banks  received  the  annuities  when  turned  in, 
and  were  required  to  bring  the  summary  proceedings  allowed 
agaiQst  the  debtor  in  case  of  default. 

The  business  of  the  rent  charge  banks  reached  its  highest 
point  about  1859,  and  as  it  fell  off  the  banks  were  dissolved. 
Prussia's  were  dissolved  along  with  the  rest,  but  they  were 
reopened  in  1891,  to  help  carry  out  the  plans  of  that  king- 
dom for  dividing  up  large  estates  for  allotment  among  the 
peasantry.  Seven  rent  charge  banks  stiU  exist  in  Prussia 
and  operate  in  connection  with  the  general  commissions. 
Their  functions  now  are  to  acquire  in  behalf  of  the  com- 
missions lands  to  be  split  up  into  small  holdings,  to  make 
loans  to  incorporated  or  cooperative  bodies  which  desire  to 
acquire  lands  for  this  purpose,  and  to  lend  to  individuals 
directly  for  buying  or  improving  small  homesteads. 

The  commissions  have  fixed  various  sizes  for  such  home- 
steads. With  one  the  minimum  is  2.5  and  the  maximum  75 
acres ;  with  another  the  limits  are  5  and  45  acres ;  while  some 
allow  from  7.5  up  to  175  acres.  The  purchaser  of  a  home- 
stead gives  in  return  a  mortgage  against  which  the  bank  issues 
three  per  cent  debentures.  The  loan  contract  provides  that 
he  shall  pay  the  interest  on  the  debentures  and  a  certain  per- 
centage of  the  principal  each  year.  If  the  annuity  thus 
formed  is  4.5  per  cent,  the  debt  wiU  become  extinguished  in 
56  years  and  one  month.  If  it  is  four  per  cent,  it  will  run  for 
60  years  and  six  months.  No  advance  payments  axe  allowed 
imtil  ten  years  after  the  date  of  the  loan. 

The  state  invalidity  and  old-age  insurance  institutions 
created  by  law  in  1889  are  public  bodies,  so  the  loans  made 
by  them  may  be  considered  as  coming  from  the  state.    There 


100  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

are  in  Germany  31  of  these  institutions,  besides  ten  offices  for 
collecting  premiums  which  have  funds  of  their  own,  drawn 
from  miners,  seafaring  persons,  and  railroad  employees.  The 
assets  of  these  institutions  may  be  legally  invested  in  mort- 
gages and  real-estate  securities,  but  they  rarely  make  loans 
directly  to  individuals.  Their  credit  is  extended  to  or  through 
cooperative  societies,  or  communal  or  other  semi-public  and 
non-profit-making  corporations.  The  rate  of  interest  ranges 
from  3  to  3.75  per  cent. 


CHAPTEE   XI 

PRIVATE    SOUECES    OF    LAND    CREDIT   IN   GERMANY 

Long-term  Reducible  Loans  Made  by  Public  Credit  Institutions. — 
Short-term  Loans  Represented  by  Second  Mortgages. — Savings 
Banks. — Their  Operation. — Mortgage  Loans. — ^Private  Insurance 
Institutions. — ^Real-estate  Loans  Not  on  Farm  Lands. — Co- 
operative Credit  Societies. — ^Land-credit  Banks. — History. — Bonds. 
— Official  Supervision. — Operation. — Bavarian  Mortgage  and  Ex- 
change Bank  of  Munich. — ^Prussian  Central  Land-credit  Com- 
pany.— History  and  Operation. 

Neaelt  all  long-term  reducible  loans  in  Germany  are 
made  by  the  landschafts  and  public,  or  semi-public,  credit  in- 
stitutions. The  reason  is  easily  explained.  Such  loans,  repay- 
able by  annuities  running  through  periods  of  many  years, 
cannot  be  made  out  of  funds  subject  to  recall.  If  the  money 
is  raised  by  the  sale  of  debentures,  they  must  have  no  fixed 
maturity  if  amortization  of  the  loans  is  planned.  But  instru- 
ments of  this  kind,  depriving  the  holders  of  the  right  of  de- 
manding the  principal  of  their  investments,  cannot  be  sold 
in  quantities  unless  guaranteed  by  the  government  or  a  con- 
cern connected  with  it ;  at  least,  this  has  proved  to  be  the  case 
in  Europe.  The  loans  from  private  sources  are  generally  for 
short  term,  that  is,  under  ten  years,  and  are  repayable  in  lump 
or  in  a  few  instalments. 

A  very  great  part  of  the  credit  accorded  by  individuals  on 
real  estate  in  Germany  is  represented  by  second  mortgages. 
The  volume  of  this  business  is  large,  because  the  land-credit 
institutions,  public  and  private,  are  so  conservative  in  their 
appraisals  that  the  one-half,  three-fifths  or  two-thirds  of  the 
land's  value,  to  which  the  amount  of  their  loans  is  restricted, 
leaves  a  wide  margin  for  credit  upon  which  their  borrowers 

101 


102  ETJEAL   CREDITS 

realize  from  other  lenders  at  high  interest  rates.  With  a  few 
exceptions,  however,  all  loans  made  by  incorporated  bodies 
are  secured  by  first  mortgages. 

The  private  institutions  which  are  the  heaviest  buyers  of 
real-estate  mortgages  in  Germany  are  the  savings  banks,  the 
insurance  companies,  and  the  joint  stock  land-credit  banks. 
These  concerns  make  loans  ptirely  for  profit;  in  this  respect 
they  differ  from  the  landschafts  and  public  institutions,  aU 
of  which  grant  credit  without  thought  of  gain.  The  interest 
rates  of  the  private  institutions,  however,  are  very  little 
higher  than  those  of  the  latter.  Apart  from  this  slight  dif- 
ference, the  chief  advantage  which  the  landschafts  and  public 
institutions  can  offer  over  the  others  is  their  ability  to  grant 
long-term,  amortizable  loans. 

The  savings  banks  are  the  greatest  source  of  land  credit 
for  the  farmers  of  small  and  medium-sized  estates  in  Ger- 
many. Most  of  the  German  savings  baaks  are  public  cor- 
porations, founded,  managed,  supervised  or  guaranteed  by  a 
province,  district,  commune  or  municipality.  They  are  non- 
profit-making, so  they  are  exempt  from  taxation.  Surplus 
earnings  go  into  reserves  or  are  devoted  to  some  philanthropic 
object.  Nevertheless,  they  carry  on  their  business  along  very 
practical  lines.  Their  maia  purpose  is  to  encourage  thrift, 
so  they  aim  to  give  depositors  as  much  interest  on  their 
money  as  can  be  obtained  from  safe  investments. 

As  far  back  as  1831  the  formation  of  savings  banks  in 
rural  districts  began;  there  are  now  368  rural  savings  banks. 
In  1910  there  were,  including  both  urban  and  rural  institu- 
tions, 2,844  public  savings  banks  with  7,404  branches,  and 
228  private  savings  banks  with  294  branches,  or  a  savings 
bank  in  nearly  every  farming  community  in  the  Empire. 
At  least  20  per  cent  of  their  assets  is  invested  in  farm  mort- 
gages. 

One-fourth  of  "the  rural  mortgages  of  the  savings  banks 
in  Prussia,  and  perhaps  a  similar  proportion  in  many  other 
German  states,  are  reducible  loans.  They  were  made  in  com- 
pliance with  the  urgent  request  of  the  Government,  which 
began  in  1886  to  call  upon  the  savings  banks  to  help  to  relieve 


PRIVATE  SOTJECES  OP  LAND  CEEDIT      103 

the  farmers  from  their  biirdensome  mortgage  indebtedness. 
The  method  of  amortization  used,  however,  is  misatisfactory. 
Its  plan  has  been  described  in  a  previous  chapter.  The  chief 
advantage  in  it  is  that  the  banks  usually  surrender  the  right 
to  recall  such  reducible  loans. 

All  the  other  mortgage  loans  of  the  savings  banks  are, 
after  the  first  year,  subject  to  recall  on  three  or  six  months' 
notice,  regardless  of  the  length  of  the  term  specified  in  the 
contract.  The  extent  of  the  credit  accorded  on  a  piece  of 
property  is  usually  one-half  to  two-thirds  of  its  value,  but 
three-fourths  and  even  five-sixths  of  the  value  is  allowed  on 
reducible  loans  on  small  holdings,  provided  the  contribution 
to  the  sinking  fund  is  one-half  of  one  per  cent  or  over  of  the 
principal  each  year. 

If  the  land  has  been  valued  by  a  landschaft  or  a  public 
credit  institution,  the  savings  banks  will  accept  its  valuation 
and  thus  save  the  applicant  the  expense  of  an  appraisal. 
Loans  as  small  as  $500  are  frequently  granted.  The  interest 
rate  is  never  over  five  per  cent.  More  than  one  half  of  the 
loans  bear  interest  at  between  five  and  four  per  cent,  over  one 
third  of  them  at  four  per  cent,  and  many  at  only  three  per 
cent. 

The  private  insurance  institutions  of  Germany  are  classi- 
fied according  to  the  business  they  carry  on,  as  life,  fire,  trans- 
portation, accident,  hail,  cattle,  glass,  burglary  and  reinsur- 
ance. As  to  organization  they  are  either  mutual  societies  or 
joint-stock  companies.  Over  two-thirds  of  their  enormous 
funds  is  invested  in  real-estate  mortgages,  but  only  an  insig- 
nificant portion  of  them  are  farm  loans. 

Most  of  the  loans  granted  by  the  private  insurance  com- 
panies may  be  recalled  on  three  or  six  months'  notice.  The 
reducible  loans  cannot  be  recalled  imtil  after  a  term  of  years. 
Amortization,  however,  is  not  practiced  to  any  considerable 
extent.  No  sum  larger  than  $50,000  can  be  loaned  on  one 
piece  of  property.  If  an  applicant  asks  for  a  loan  exceeding 
$35,000,  the  property  must  be  appraised  by  experts,  usually 
selected  from  a  landschaft,  public  institution,  or  chamber  of 
agriculture  in  the  locality.    The  legal  limit  to  credit  is  three- 


104  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

fifths  the  Taluation  of  the  property.  In  some  states  two-thirds 
of  the  value  has  been  specified.  The  interest  rate  averages 
about  4.4  per  cent,  to  which  must  be  added  in  the  first  year  a 
commission  of  at  least  one  per  cent,  which  most  of  the  insur- 
ance companies  retain  from  the  principal  at  the  time  of  mak- 
ing the  loan. 

The  cooperative  credit  societies  of  the  Eaiffeisen  type  in 
Germany  frequently  take  mortgages  on  their  loans,  but  the 
security  is  considered  secondary  to  the  personal  obligation  of 
the  borrower.  The  mortgage  business  is  carried  on  not  so 
much  as  a  matter  of  profitable  investment  for  their  funds  as 
for  dotag  a  service  for  their  members.  A  mortgage  is  some- 
times placed  on  the  property  of  a  borrowing  member  simply 
to  protect  it  from  other  possible  creditors.  Again,  if  a  mem- 
ber wishes  to  buy  out  the  rights  of  a  co-heir  or  to  acquire  a 
small  farm,  his  society  wiU  invariably  advance  him  the  money 
therefor  on  mortgage.  Loans  of  this  kind  usually  run  for 
ten  years  or  longer  and  are  repayable  in  instalments.  Some 
of  the  rural  credit  societies  are  authorized  to  issue  deben- 
tures. Professor  Eobert  MuUy  von  Oppenried  estimated  that 
in  1908  the  mortgage  holdings  of  all  the  cooperative  societies 
belongiug  to  the  Imperial  Federation  totaled  $43,203,000. 
They  have  probably  increased  since  that  year.  In  Bavaria 
and  some  of  the  other  German  states  statutes  have  been  en- 
acted which  give  cooperative  societies  the  option  of  buying 
all  agricultural  lands  which  are  offered  for  sale,  for  subsequent 
resale  to  members. 

The  joiat-stock  companies  known  as  land-credit  banks 
numbered  38  in  1912.  The  aggregate  of  their  capital  and 
assets  is  enormous,  but  only  one-sixth  of  their  mortgage  hold- 
ings are  farm  loans,  while  ninety-one  per  cent  of  this  one- 
sixth  is  in  the  hands  of  one  Prussian  and  seven  Bavarian 
banks. 

The  first  private  banking  concern  to  accord  land  credit  in 
Germany  was  the  Pomeranian  Eitterschaft  Bank,  founded  in 
1824.  The  oldest  land-credit  bank  with  shares  owned  by  pri- 
vate individuals  is  the  Bavarian  Mortgage  and  Exchange 
Bank  of  Munich.    This  was  founded  in  1834  for  a  discount. 


PEIVATE  SOUECES  OF  LAND  CREDIT      105 

deposit,  savings,  and  fire-  and  life-insurance  business.  It  was 
authorized  to  issue  notes  up  to  four-tenths  of  its  capital  of 
$4,280,000.  These  were  to  be  legal  tender,  and  three-fourths 
of  the  issue  had  to  be  secured  by  mortgages.  Hence  the  main 
reason  for  taking  mortgages  was  as  a  security  for  these  notes. 
The  Bavarian  Mortgage  and  Exchange  Bank  did  not  develop 
into  a  regular  land-credit  hank  until  1864.  The  first  private 
bank  which  had  a  special  purpose  from  the  start  to  extend 
credit  to  landowners  was  organized  at  Dessau  in  1846,  but  it 
no  longer  continues  as  a  land-credit  institution.  The  oldest 
existing  bank  founded  especially  for  this  purpose  is  the  Credit 
Institution  for  AU  Germany,  which  was  organized  at  Leip- 
zig iu  1858,  but  has  issued  no  debentures  since  1899. 

The  mortgage  operations  of  all  these  early  banks  were 
handled  in  departments  separate  from  their  regular  business. 
Apart  from  the  institutions  mentioned,  all  existing  companies 
(down  to  1912)  were  created  since  1862.  Twenty-seven  of 
them  came  into  existence  within  11  years  after  that  date. 
Eight  were  organized  within  two  years  between  1894  and 
1896.    One  was  founded  in  1886. 

All  these  banks  were  chartered  by  special  administrative 
or  legislative  acts  or  under  provincial  laws.  There  was  no 
national  and  general  law  for  land-credit  banks  until  1899. 
In  that  year  the  Imperial  legislature  enacted  a  law  for  form- 
ing such  banks  and  regulating  their  business.  Only  one  bank 
has  been  formed  under  this  law,  but  all  the  37  banks  men- 
tioned complied  with  its  terms  and  have  received  licenses 
under  it. 

This  law  has  nothing  to  do  with  the  landschafts  or  public 
credit  institutions.  It  relates  only  to  private  concerns  which 
issue  bonds  or  debentures  against  mortgages.  It  forbids  all 
except  joint-stock  companies  and  limited  partnerships  from 
issuing  such  bonds,  and  requires  that  license  be  obtained  be- 
fore beginning  business.  This  license  may  be  obtained  from 
a  state  imless  loans  are  intended  to  be  made  in  two  or  more 
states,  when  it  must  be  obtained  from  the  Imperial  authori- 
ties. The  chief  object  of  the  law  is  to  make  the  bonds  a  stand- 
ardized and  safe  investment.     No   special  privileges  have 


106  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

been  accorded  to  the  banks.  The  provisions  are  regulatory 
and  restrictive. 

The  banks  which  may  be  authorized  to  issue  bonds  are 
either  pure  or  mixed  land-credit  concerns.  The  former  limit 
their  business  to  loans  on  mortgage  and  the  issuance  of  bonds, 
the  purchase  and  sale  of  real-estate  securities,  the  granting  of 
loans  to  mimicipalities  and  public  utility-corporations,  the 
purchase  and  sale  of  stocks  and  bonds  on  commission,  the  re- 
ceipt of  deposits  not  to  exceed  one-half  of  their  paid-in  capital, 
and  the  collection  of  bank  paper.  The  latter  are  similar  to 
American  trust  companies  and  are  not  favored  by  the  Govern- 
ment. They  number  eight,  and  perhaps  no  others  will  be 
chartered. 

Official  supervision  is  prescribed  but  it  is  left  to  the  states 
in  which  the  banks  do  business.  It  embraces  all  the  dealings 
of  the  bank,  and  is  exercised  through  a  state  bureau  and  a 
fiduciary  agent  appointed  for  each  bank.  The  state  may 
demand  a  special  report  on  any  transaction  and  may  send  a 
representative  to  the  meetings  of  stockholders,  directors,  and 
officers.  The  fiduciary  agent  has  joint  custody  with  the  offi- 
cers of  the  bank  to  which  he  is  assigned  of  aU  papers  con- 
nected with  the  bonds.  He  has  absolute  custody  of  the  mort- 
gages used  as  security  for  the  bonds.  He  holds  the  mortgages 
as  a  trustee,  and  must  attach  his  signature  to  all  bonds  issued 
to  certify  that  they  are  sufficiently  covered  by  mortgages  de- 
posited in  his  care.  Consequently  these  bonds  are  not  deben- 
tures, because  they  are  secured  by  specified  mortgages.  As 
mortgages  are  paid  off,  others  must  be  turned  over  to  the 
fiduciary  agent. 

Loans  cannot  be  made  abroad,  nor  in  any  state  from 
which  the  bank  has  not  obtained  a  license.  A  loan  may  not 
exceed  three-fifths  of  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  land,  except 
in  the  ease  of  farm  loans,  for  which  a  state  may  allow  two- 
thirds  of  the  value  as  the  limit.  No  property  may  be  taken 
on  mortgage  which  does  not  yield  a  steady  income.  One-half 
of  the  total  of  farm  loans  made  by  a  bank  must  be  reducible 
by  an  annual  payment  equal  to  at  least  one-fourth  per  cent  of 
the  principal.     Borrowers  have  the  right  to  make  advance 


PEIVATE  SOUECES  OP  LAND  CEEDIT      107 

payments  but  may  agree  to  defer  this  right  for  ten  years. 
The  instalment  paid  in  advance  on  reducible  loans  must  be 
large  enough  to  shorten  the  term  of  the  contract  by  one  or 
more  years,  but  if  a  borrower  has  paid  up  one-tenth  of  his 
loan,  he  may  demand  that  the  bank  arrange  a  new  scheme 
of  amortization  for  him  with  a  smaller  annuity. 

The  bonds  issued  by  a  bank  must  always  be  covered  by  an 
equal  amount  of  mortgages  bearing  at  least  the  same  rate  of 
interest  placed  in  the  custody  of  the  fiduciary  agent.  No 
premiums  or  prizes  are  allowed  upon  the  redemption  of  the 
bonds.  In  the  event  of  the  dissolution  of  a  bank,  the  bond- 
holders have  a  claim  on  the  mortgages  registered  for  their 
security  against  all  other  creditors.  The  total  of  bonds  out- 
standing must  never  exceed  for  a  pure  land-credit  bank  15 
times  its  paid-in  share  capital  and  a  special  reserve  designed 
to  meet  any  deficit  that  might  occur.  Mixed  banks  cannot 
issue  bonds  in  excess  of  ten  times  this  limit,  but  some  which 
had  the  right  before  the  passage  of  the  law  to  issue  bonds  to 
20  times  that  Umit  have  been  left  in  possession  of  it. 

At  the  last  calculation,  58.48  per  cent  of  the  bonds  of  the 
German  land-credit  banks  bore  four  per  cent  interest,  39.65 
per  cent  of  them  3.5  per  cent,  and  the  remainder  3.75  and  4.5 
per  cent.  The  interest  on  the  mortgages  was  usually  about 
one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  higher,  plus  costs  and  commissions. 
Most  of  the  banks  have  paid  at  least  seven. per  cent  or  more 
in  dividends  regularly  for  many  years. 

The  lack  of  success  of  the  Grerman  land-credit  banks  as 
regards  farm  loans  has  been  attributed  to  various  causes.  But 
the  trouble  seems  to  be  that  only  a  few  of  them  have  the 
necessary  size  and  standing  to  enable  them  to  sell  bonds  which 
have  no  fixed  time  for  maturity,  and  that  in  consequence  of 
their  inability  to  raise  money  by  such  instruments,  they  are 
not  in  a  position  to  grant  long-term,  reducible  loans  of  the 
kind  needed  by  agriculture.  The  proof  of  this  lies  in  the 
fact  that  the  two  big  banks  which  have  gained  the  confidence 
of  the  investing  public  do  a  large  farm-mortgage  business, 
nearly  all  of  which  is  on  the  amortization  plan  and  repre- 
sented by  debentures  not  recallable  by  the  holders. 


108  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

These  two  concerns  are  the  Bavarian  Mortgage  and  Ex- 
change Bank  of  Munich  and  the  Prussian  Central  Land 
Credit  Company.  The  "King  and  Queen  of  Bavaria  and  high 
state  officials  were  charter  members  of  the  former  when  it 
was  founded  in  1835.  The  latter,  which  was  established  in 
1870  with  the  special  object  of  aidiag  agriculture,  is  a  semi- 
public  institution.  The  Bavarian  bank  has  paid  over  12 
per  cent  dividends  since  1890;  from  1907  to  1911  it  paid  13 
per  cent.  The  Prussian  bank  is  the  more  important  of  the 
two,  siace  its  operations  extend  over  the  entire  Empire. 

The  Prussian  Central  Land  Credit  Company,  a  joiat-stoek 
corporation,  was  the  outcome  of  the  efforts  of  Prince  Bis- 
marck to  create  a  national  mortgage  institution  for-  the  great 
Empire  that  he  was  forming.  He  assisted  three  powerful 
banking  houses  to  obtaia  a  charter  by  a  special  law,  and  he 
persuaded  France,  whom  Germany  was  about  to  fight,  to 
order  the  then  president  of  the  Credit  Fonder  to  serve  on  its 
board  of  directors.  The  government  bank  of  Prussia  bought 
a  large  block  of  stock  so  as  to  give  the  new  concern  prestige 
and  aid  its  first  ventures.  The  headquarters  of  the  company 
are  at  Berlin  and  between  three  and  four  hundred  agents  are 
scattered  throughout  the  Empire.  It  is  authorized  to  do  busi- 
ness anywhere  in  Germany  but  most  of  its  loans  are  confined 
to  Prussia. 

The  bank  is  supervised  by  a  special  royal  commissioner 
imder  the  Prussian  Ministry  of  Agriculture,  Public  Domains 
and  Forests.  The  stockholders  at  their  general  meeting  elect 
three  auditors  for  three  years  to  examine  the  loans  and  over- 
see the  management.  They  elect  also  18  directors,  among 
whom  they  designate  one  president  and  three  vice-presidents 
to  be  appointed  by  the  King.  The  directors,  who  must  be 
citizens  of  Prussia,  serve  for  ten  years.  The  bank  operates 
under  the  law  of  1899,  so  far  as  it  does  not  interfere  with  its 
special  privileges. 

The  original  capital  stock  of  the  Prussian  Central  Land 
Credit  Company  was  $8,640,000;  it  has  been  increased  to 
$10,656,000.  The  company  may  issue  mortgage  loans  up  to 
20  times  its  original  stock  and  15  times  the  increase.    It  may 


PKIVATE  SOURCES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT      109 

issue  conummal  bonds  up  to  34  times  the  original  stock  and 
18  times  the  increase.  The  intention  was  to  make  the  bank 
distinctively  a  land-credit  company,  but  it  soon  drifted  from 
this  course  and  began  to  lend  largely  to  municipalities  and 
public-utility  corporations  and  to  receive  deposits.  These 
were  powers  granted  by -its  charter.  Today,  however,  it  has 
become  a  land-credit  institution  second  only  to  two  in  Ger- 
many. 

The  bank  has  $165,200,412.72  in  farm  loans,  $134,627,- 
556.72  in  loans  on  city  properties,  and  $44,386,643.28  in  loans 
to  municipalities.  Against  these  loans  it  has  bonds  outstanding 
to  the  total  of  $235,769,940.  The  smallest  loan  granted  is 
$250,  and  the  largest  $1,440,000.  Two-thirds  of  the  value 
is  the  largest  loan  that  will  be  granted  on  any  piece  of  prop- 
erty. The  value  may  be  ascertained  by  the  experts  of  the 
bank  or  by  a  landschaft  or  public  credit  institution,  or  the 
bank  may  take  22.5  times  the  figure  calculated  by  the  public 
officials  as  the  annual  income  of  the  property  for  taxation, 
provided  the  income  does  not  surpass  four  or  five  per  cent  of 
the  capitalized  value.  t 

Borrowers  now  pay  4.25  or  4.50  per  cent  interest.  Besides, 
they  pay  a  commission  composed  of  one  per  cent  as  a  tax  to 
the  state,  one-half  of  one  per  cent  to  the  bank  for  profit,  and 
one  to  one  and  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  to  cover  the  cost  of 
busiaess.  This  amounts  to  somewhere  between  two  and  three 
per  cent  over  the  interest  rate  for  the  first  year.  In  addition 
they  pay  a  contribution  to  the  sinking  fund.  Over  two-thirds 
of  the  farm  mortgages  are  reducible  by  amortization.  Most 
pay  one-half  of  one  per  cent;  this  extinguishes  the  loan  in 
561^  years.  Others  pay  one  per  cent;  this  extinguishes  the 
loan  in  44  years.  Only  first  mortgages  are  taken.  Foreclosures 
rarely  occur  on  farms.  About  one  foreclosure  for  146  loans: 
is  the  average  on  city  properties.  A  borrower  cannot  demand 
that  the  bank  take  an  advance  payment  until  ten  years  after 
the  loan  has  been  made ;  thereafter  he  may  repay  his  loan  as 
fast  as  he  pleases. 

Debentures  may  not  be  issued  by  the  Prussian  Central 
Land  Credit  Company  at  a  rate  of  interest  lower  than  that 


110  ETJRAL   CEEDITS 

of  the  mortgages  by  which  they  are  secured.  At  present 
bonds  are  drawing  four  per  cent  and  are  selling  at  96.  The 
smallest  denomination  is  $24  and  the  highest  is  $1,200.  The 
bonds  are  payable  to  bearer,  without  fixed  time  for  maturity. 
They  are  recallable  at  the  will  of  the  bank.  Sometimes  it 
redeems  them  in  series,  and  at  other  times  by  indiyidual  num- 
bers. The  communal  debentures  may  be  used  by  trustees  for 
the  investment  of  the  funds  in  their  care,  but  the  mortgage 
debentures  have  no  privileges.  No  debentures  may  be  issued 
imless  the  royal  commissioner  certifies  by  his  signature  upon 
them  that  they  are  sufficiently  covered  by  underlying  mort- 
gages, equal  iu  amount  and  beariag  at  least  the  same  rate  of 
interest  of  such  mortgages. 

The  lowest  dividend  the  bank  has  ever  paid  was  seven  per 
cent,  and  this  was  for  the  first  year.  For  43  years  the  divi- 
dends have  averaged  8.75  per  cent.  In  1912  they  were  9.5 
per  cent.    The  reserves  are  about  41  per  cent  of  the  capital. 


CHAPTER  XII 

FRANCE:    THE    CE:1EDIT    FONCIEB 

Legislation. — History  of  Land-credit  Movement. — Creation  of  the 
Credit  Foncier. — Privileges. — Organization. — Capital  Stock. — 
Purpose. — ^Two  Sources  of  Funds. — ^Long-term  Loans. — Syndieal 
Associations. — ^Long-term  Leases. — ^Amount  of  Loan. — Applica- 
tion for  Loan. — The  Purge. — Terms  and  Penalties. — Use  of  De- 
bentures.— ^Premiums. — Special  Privileges. 

The  legislation  on  land  credit  in  France  comprises  the  \ 
law  of  1852  on  bond  and  mortgage  institutions,  the  law  of 
1906  on  long-term  credit  for  agricultural  cooperative  associa- 
tions, and  the  law  of  1910  on  long-term  credit  for  small  home- 
steaders. This  legislation  furnishes  striking  instances  of  state 
aid  and  special  privilege. 

In  the  beginning  of  the  last  century  land-credit  facilities 
in  France  were  in  bad  condition,  mainly  because  of  defective 
laws  regarding  the  registration  of  instruments  affecting  the 
title  or  possession  of  land.  A  lender  who  took  a  mortgage 
was  never  sure  of  recovering  his  claim  in  ease  of  foreclosure. 
Consequently  money  was  scarce  and  usury  rife.  The  land  was 
so  heavily  encumbered  with  debts  which  had  been  accumu- 
lating for  generations  that  its  returns  were  barely  sufficient 
to  pay  taxes  and  annual  dues. 

In  1826,  when  farmers  and  landowners  were  on  the  verge 
of  bankruptcy,  Casimir  Perier  offered  a  prize  for  the  best 
answers  to  the  following  questions: 

What  are  the  defects  and  deficiencies  in  the  rrench  laws 
relating  to  mortgage  loans? 

What  are  the  obstacles  which  deter  capital  from  seeking 
such  investments  ? 

Ill 


112  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

What  -would  be  the  best  plan  to  adopt  for  the  purpose  of 
framing  a  complete  project  for  settling  these  problems  in  a  -way 
which  would  be  most  in  harmony  with  the  needs  of  the  public 
treasury  and  building  contractors  and  with  the  security  re- 
quired by  lenders? 

M.  Perier's  offer  started  a  movement  that  lasted  26  years 
and  produced  a  volumiQous  literature  which  is  the  best  ever 
written  on  land  credit.  Counting  everything  relating  to  the 
eubject,  according  to  Joaquin  Diaz  de  Eabago,  over  two  hun- 
dred plans  and  systems  were  proposed  and  discussed.  Four 
writers  were  equally  prominent  in  this  long  campaign. 

In  1839  Louis  Wolowski,  a  young  man  who  subsequently 
became  one  of  the  organizers  of  the  first  land  bank,  submitted 
to  the  Academy  of  Moral  and  Political  Science  an  essay  which 
gave  to  France  her  first  information  on  the  German  land- 
schafts.  Inspired  by  this  pamphlet  the  French  Government 
sent  a  special  commissioner,  Charles  Edward  Eoyer,  of  the 
Ministry  of  Agriculture,  to  Germany  and  Belgium  in  1844 
to  make  an  investigation  of  their  land-credit  institutions.  M. 
tEloyer  died  in  1847  at  the  age  of  37,  but  his  remarkable  re- 
port, compiled  after  a  few  months  of  travel,  left  a  profound 
and  permanent  impression  upon  students  and  legislators. 

A  few  years  later  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  appointed  a 
commission  of  three  to  make  further  investigations.  The 
report  of  its  secretary,  Jean  Baptiste  Josseau,  rendered  in 
1851,  covered  nearly  all  the  European  countries  in  which 
land-credit  institutions  then  existed.  In  the  same  year  the 
Chegaray  report  was  presented  on  behalf  of  a  legislative  com- 
mittee to  which  had  been  assigned  the  duty  of  examining  the 
various  projects  submitted  to  the  National  Assembly.  This 
document  is  a  comprehensive  account  of  the  entire  land- 
credit  movement  in  France.  It  summarized  all  the  material 
which  had  been  accumulated  and  analyzed  the  projects  at 
length.  Hence  the  French  people,  then  thoroughly  aroused, 
ihad  before  them  all  available  information ;  and  it  led  directly 
to  the  idea  of  the  long-term  loan  repayable  by  annuities  and 
the  issue  of  debentures  without  fixed  maturity. 


FEANCE:    THE    CEEDIT   FONCIEE  113 

The  law  of  1853  was  the  result  of  the  movement  started 
by  Casimir  Perier.  Various  amendments  have  been  made  in 
details  but  its  basic  principles  remain  unaltered.  The  law  is 
divided  into  five  parts.  The  first  specifies  the  functions  of 
land-credit  institutions  and  the  ways  in  which  they  may  be 
organized;  the  second  lays  down  rules  for  making  loans,  and 
the  third,  for  issuing  debentures;  the  fourth  prescribes  the 
measures  to  be  taken  for  adjij^icating  titles  and  protecting 
loans  against  the  claims  of  third  parties,  and  the  methods  of 
recovery  against  borrowers ;  and  the  fifth  enumerates  the  spe- 
cial privileges  and  restrictions  under  which  the  business  must 
be  conducted.  For  aiding  any  institutions  that  might  be 
formed,  the  law  authorized  the  national  government  and  the 
departments  to  purchase  certain  quantities  of  their  debentures 
each  year,  and  also  appropriated  $2,000,000  to  be  allotted 
among  them.  The  reformation  of  the  mortgage  and  registra- 
tion laws  was  left  to  subsequent  legislation ;  instead  the  land- 
credit  institutions  were  given  a  special  procedure  for  purging 
titles. 

The  law  did  not  express  any  preference  for  the  association 
of  borrowers  (landschaft)  or  the  joint-stock  company.  It 
declared  that  both  might  be  formed,  but  no  landschaft  was 
ever  created  in  France.  A  number  of  companies,  however, 
came  into  existence  shortly  after  the  passage  of  the  act.  The 
Land  Bank  of  Paris  was  chartered  on  March  38 ;  of  Marseilles, 
on  September  13;  of  Nevers,  on  October  20,  1853.  Others 
were  started  at  Lyons,  Toulouse,  Orleans,  Poitiers,  Limoges, 
Eouen,  Bordeaux:,  and  Brest  in  the  same  year :  in  fact  the  Gov- 
ernment then  favored  a  plurality  of  institutions  and  intended 
that  one  should  be  established  for  each  department.  But 
doubts  soon  arose  as  to  the  advisability  of  such  a  plan.  Fear 
was  felt  that  a  large  number  of  institutions  could  not  be 
properly  supervised  and  compelled  to  conduct  their  business 
along  proper  lines.  Moreover,  the  trouble  which  the  district 
banks  had  encountered  in  the  then  recent  panic  of  1848  was 
recalled  as  a  danger  that  might  result  from  competing  com- 
panies. These  small  commercial  banks,  which  had  been 
formed  during  good  times,  throve  so  long  as  the  calm  lasted. 


114  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

but  when  the  crisis  occiirredj  and  when  their  assistance  would 
have  been  most  useful  to  trade  and  commerce,  on  account  of 
their  meagre  capital  and  resources,  some  were  obliged  to  cease 
operations  and  others  to  suspend  payment,  and  they  escaped 
complete  ruin  only  by  consolidating  with  the  Bank  of  France. 

After  a  few  months'  trial  with  several  companies  in  the 
field,  therefore,  France  decided  that  centralization  and  unity 
of  action  were  better  than  competition,  and  proceeded  to 
establish  a  large  central  institution  with  agencies  throughout 
the  nation,  which  should  make  loans  upon  the  same  general 
conditions  and  issue  debentures  of  standard  types.  On  De- 
cember 10,  1852,  Emperor  Napoleon  III  promulgated  a 
decree  which  extended  the  powers  of  the  Land  Bank  of 
Paris,  the  first  company  organized,  to  all  departments  in 
which  no  companies  yet  existed,  conferred  upon  it  the  title 
La  Societe  du  Credit  Foncier  de  France,  authorized  it  to 
absorb  the  other  companies  which  had  been  formed,  turned 
over  to  it  the  appropriation  of  $2,000,000  (which  has  never 
been  repaid),  and  granted  it  a  monopoly  of  25  years. 

A  decree  of  1853  allowed  the  Credit  Foncier  to  award 
prizes  by  lot  upon  the  recall  for  payment  of  its  land  deben- 
tures. A  decree  of  1854  provided  that  its  president  and  two 
vice-presidents  should  be  appointed  by  the  Emperor,  and  that 
three  of  its  directors  should  be  selected  from  the  Ministry 
of  Finance.  In  1856  it  absorbed  the  land  banks  of  Marseilles 
and  Nevers.  A  decree  of  1858  substituted  the  Credit  Foncier 
in  place  of  the  state  for  financing  drainage  projects  and  au- 
thorized it  to  issue  debentures  guaranteed  by  the  state  for 
this  purpose.  The  inonopoly  was  not  renewed,  but  the  free 
subsidy  and  permanent  special  privileges  mentioned  and 
others  later  granted  have  enabled  it  to  overcome  aU  competi- 
tors. It  is  the  only  mortgage-bond  company  of  consequence 
lending  on  land  situated  in  France.  Its  charter  embodies 
the  main  provisions  of  the  law  of  1852,  so  there  is  no  need 
to  discuss  the  law  apart  from  the  charter  and  by-laws  of 
the  company. 

The  president  of  the  Credit  Foncier  (land  credit)  must 
hold  200  shares  of  the  company's  stock.    His  salary  is  $8,000. 


FEANCE:   THE   CEEDIT   FONCIEK  115 

He  is  the  representative  of  the  state  and  has  control  over  all 
affairs  not  otherwise  assigned.  He  holds  oflBce  during  good 
behavior,  as  do  also  the  two  vice-presidents  who  perform  such 
duties  as  are  delegated  to  them  by  the  president.  Each  vice- 
president  draws  a  salary  of  $4,000.  Each  must  hold  100 
shares  of  stock.  Shares  so  held  are  inalienable  during  the 
terms  of  ofBce,  and  are  deposited  with  the  company  as  a 
guaranty  for  good  conduct.  Besides  these  officers  the  Credit 
Foncier  has  a  board  of  directors,  auditors,  and  a  general  as- 
sembly of  shareholders. 

The  board  of  directors  is  composed  of  the  president;  at 
least  20  stockholders;  the  vice-presidents  and  auditors,  who, 
however,  have  no  vote;  and  three  high  ofiBcials  of  the  Ministry 
of  Finance.  They  receive  a  per  diem  for  attendance  at  meet- 
ings. Five  of  the  members  are  retired  each  year  by  order  of 
seniority  but  are  eligible  for  reelection.  The  board  exercises 
all  powers  not  reserved  exclusively  to  the  president  and  other 
officials. 

The  auditors  must  also  be  stockholders.  They  receive  a 
reasonable  compensation.  They  watch  over  the  affairs  of  the 
company,  especially  the  records  and  accounts,  the  issuing  of 
debentures,  and  the  proper  execution  of  the  laws  and  the  by- 
laws. Their  powers,  however,  are  limited  to  making  reports 
and  calling  special  meetings  of  the  stockholders  whenever  they 
deem  it  advisable. 

The  general  assembly  is  composed  of  the  200  stockholders 
holding  the  largest  number  of  shares,  but  40  constitute  a 
quorum  if  they  own  one-tenth  of  aU  the  shares  which  have 
been  issued.  It  meets  regularly  once  a  year  on  15  days'  notice 
published  in  the  two  official  newspapers.  The  president  pre- 
sides. Two  stockholders  having  the  largest  number  of  shares 
act  as  tellers.  Only  stockholders  may  hold  proxies.  The  ma- 
jority prevails.  Each  has  one  vote  for  every  40  shares  held, 
but  no  one  may  have  more  than  five  votes  in  his  own  name, 
nor  more  than  ten  counting  proxies.  Everyone  entitled  to 
attend  the  meeting  has  one  vote,  although  he  may  not  own 
40  shares.  The  president  and  tellers  select  the  secretary  for 
the  meetings. 


116  EHRAL   CKEDITS 

The  docket  is  prepared  by  the  president  and  board  of  di- 
rectors in  advance  of  the  meeting,  and  nothing  else  can  be 
brought  before  the  assembly  during  the  sessions.  The  regular 
procedure  is  to  receive  the  reports  of  the  president  and  audi- 
tors, and  at  an  annual  meeting  to  elect  directors  and  auditors 
in  place  of  those  retiring.  Upon  proposal  of  the  president 
amendments  to  the  by-laws  may  be  made,  but  they  require  a 
two-thirds  majority  and  the  approval  of  the  Government. 
E'otice  of  the  proposal  of  amendments  also  must  be  specifi- 
cally noted  in  the  call  for  the  meeting.  The  dissolution  of 
the  company  is  likewise  determined  by  the  assembly. 

The  capital  stock  of  the  Credit  Foncier  is  now  $45,000,- 
000,  but  it  may  be  increased  to  $50,000,000,  divided  into 
500,000  non-assessable  shares  of  $100  each.  Shares  cannot  be 
bought  or  used  as  collateral  by  the  conipany  itself,  except  for 
the  temporary  possession  allowed  for  the  recovery  of  unpaid 
partial  payments  due  thereon.  Stockholders  have  the  refusal 
of  all  new  issues  proportionately  to  shares  already  held.  If 
new  issues  are  sold  above  par,  the  premium  is  placed  in  the 
special  reserve.  Shares  may  be  made  out  in  the  name  of  the 
holder  or  to  bearer;  if  the  former,  they  can  be  sold  or  trans- 
ferred only  on  the  company's  register.  Payment  on  shares 
purchased  may  be  made  in  instalments.  The  certificates  may 
be  deposited  with  the  company  for  safekeeping,  but  dividends 
in  any  case  are  considered  as  legally  paid  when  given  to 
bearer.  The  ownership  of  stock  confers  title  to  a  pro  rata 
share  of  the  profits  and  assets  but  no  right  of  action  against 
the  company  therefor.  Stockholders  must  abide  by  the  de- 
cision of  the  general  assembly  in  all  disputes  between  them 
and  the  company. 

The  capital  stock  was  designed  mainly  as  a  guaranty  for 
the  debentures  and  is  kept  largely  ia  quick  assets.  The  law 
has  strictly  prescribed  the  form  of  investment  so  as  to  render 
the  capital  stock  always  available  for  its  primary  purpose. 
One-fourth  must  be  kept  in  government  bonds,  one-fourth 
represented  by  the  company's  office  buildings,  by  loans  to 
colonies  or  countries  under  a  French  protectorate,  or  by  se- 
curities of  the  kind  used  for  collateral  by  the  Bank  of  France ; 


FRANCE:   THE   CEEDIT   PONCIER  117 

only  the  remaining  half  can  be  legally  employed  in  loan 
operations.  In  1911  no  more  than  $1,101,565  of  the  real- 
estate  loans  on  the  books  of  the  Credit  Foncier  were  made 
therefrom,  and  this  was  an  exceptional  amount,  authorized 
by  law  to  relieve  the  victims  of  the  earthquake  and  inunda- 
tions of  the  two  preceding  years.  The  balance  is  represented 
in  extensions  granted  to  debtors  in  arrears  on  their  annuities, 
the  cost  price  of  properties  taken  in  foreclosure,  commercial 
paper,  and  other  fluid  securities. 

Five  per  cent  per  annum  is  allowed  to  shareholders  out  of 
the  earnings.  After  this  dividend  has  been  paid,  the  hoard 
of  directors  must  set  aside  a  sum  between  five  per  cent  and 
20  per  cent  of  the  remainder  of  the  earnings  for  the  obliga- 
tory reserve.  The  board  may  provide  also  for  special  reserves. 
The  balance  of  the  earnings  may  be  used  for  dividends.  A 
dividend  not  claimed  within  five  years  reverts  to  the  com- 
pany. 

When  the  obligatory  reserve  equals  one-half  the  capital 
stock,  no  further  payments  may  be  made  into  it.  This  re- 
serve is  used  to  steady  the  dividends  and  assure  five  per  cent 
to  stockholders  each  year.  It  is  now  about  one-tenth  of  the 
capital  stock.  Its  investment  rests  with  the  board  of  direc- 
tors, by  whom  it  is  held  in  quick  assets. 

The  Credit  Foncier  operates  only  in  France,  Algeria  and 
Tunis.  Its  headquarters  are  at  Paris,  where,  besides  its  gen- 
eral oflSce,  it  has  large  safe-deposit  vaults  used  extensively  by 
the  public.  It  maintains  a  pension  fund  for  retired  em- 
ployees. 

The  company's  primary  purpose  is  to  lend  sums  on  mort- 
gage to  landowners,  repayable  either  at  long  term  by  annui- 
ties or  at  short  term  with  or  without  amortization,  and  to 
create  and  issue  debentures  up  to  the  amount  of  the  loans 
granted.  With  the  consent  of  the  Government,  however,  it 
may  use  any  system  which  would  facilitate  lending  on  real 
estate,  the  advancement  of  agriculture,  the  improvement  of 
the  soil,  and  the  extinction  of  the  land  debt.  It  is  authorized 
also  to  lend  with  or  without  mortgage  to  departments,  munici- 
palities, syndical  associations,  hospitals,  public  establishments, 


118  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

and  on  drainage  projects,  and  to  issue  debentures  against  these 
loans.  In  addition  to  this,  it  may  discount  the  paper  of  a 
subsidiary  building  company  called  the  Sous-Comptoir  des 
Entrepreneurs  de  Batiment,  and  also  receive  deposits  up  to 
$25,000,000. 

The  law  requires  one-fourth  of  the  deposits  to  be  kept  in 
account  current  "with  the  treasury  department  or  ia  securities 
deposited  in  lieu  thereof,  and  the  remainder  in  government 
annuities,  treasury  bonds,  and  negotiable  instruments  and 
collateral  receivable  by  the  Bank  of  Prance.  The  deposits 
may  be  loaned  on  the  security  of  the  company's  debentures. 

The  Credit  Foncier  has  two  sources  of  funds  for  its  opera- 
tions. The  first  is  its  capital  stock,  reserves  and  deposits; 
most  of  these  funds  are  employed  in  carrying  on  a  pure  bank- 
ing business  or  are  placed  in  short-term  loans  or  in  invest- 
ments specified  by  law.  The  second  is  the  money  realized 
from  the  sale  of  debentures ;  practically  all  of  this  is  used  for 
long-term  loans. 

The  long-term  loans  are  those  for  periods  between  ten  and 
75  years.  They  must  always  be  repaid  by  annuities.  Those 
imder  ten  years  are  known  as  short-term  loans.  These  alone 
may  be  repayable  in  lump  or  by  instalments.  As  already 
indicated,  certain  classes  of  borrowers  need  not  give  mortgage 
security. 

Loans  for  drainage  projects  run  for  25  years  and  are  re- 
payable by  an  annuity  of  6.41  per  cent.  If  made  to  associa- 
tions or  corporations  upon  arrangement  or  guaranty  of  the 
Government,  the  company  may  acquire  a  statutory  lien 
thereon  through  certain  legal  proceedings.  In  all  events  the 
company  has  a  right  to  the  revenues  and  crops  of  the  drained 
lands  for  its  annuities.  This  claim  is  second  only  to  taxes 
and  public  assessments  or  to  the  costs  of  making  the  crops, 
and  may  be  enforced  by  the  same  means  provided  for  recov- 
ering taxes  if  the  company  can  prove  that  the  money  was 
actually  used  for  the  purpose  for  which  it  was  lent. 

No  mortgages  need  be  taken  for  loans  to  the  departments, 
municipalities,  syndical  associations,  public-utility  corpora- 
tions, hospitals,  and  religious  and  charitable  associations.  The 


FEANCE:    THE    CREDIT   FONCIEE  119 

budgets,  valuable  assets,  large  properties,  and,  above  all,  the 
high  character  of  the  management  of  such  institutions,  have 
proved  to  be  ample  security.  The  use  of  the  long-term  loan 
with  amortization,  the  mother-idea  of  the  Credit  Fonder,  is 
peculiarly  adapted  to  them,  because  the  works  which  they 
undertake  are  usually  for  the  purpose  of  increasing  their  reve- 
nue rather  than  for  restoring  the  capital  expended.  The 
incontrovertible  usefulness  of  amortization  for  institutions 
of  this  kind  is  shown  by  the  fact  that  nearly  one  half  of  the 
outstanding  loans  have  been  made  to  them.  These  loans 
usually  run  for  periods  of  thirty  to  forty  years. 

The  syndical  associations  referred  to  are  groups  of  per- 
sons united  to  protect  or  develop  a  common  property,  to  com- 
plete projects  which  can  be  carried  out  best  by  collective  ef- 
fort, or  to  do  anything  else  to  further  their  mutual  interests. 
First  mortgages  are  required  for  loans  made  to  individuals, 
but  there  are  exceptions.  Loans  which  are  used  to  pay  off 
prior  encumbrances  are  considered  as  made  upon  first  mort- 
gage if  the  payment  results  in  putting  the  company's  lien 
above  all  others  without  any  concurrent  claims.  The  company 
retains  a  sufficient  sum  out  of  the  loan  until  these  prior  claims 
are  paid  off  or  subrogated  to  the  mortgage  taken  by  it.  This 
exception  to  the  general  rule  was  absolutely  necessary  in 
France  at  the  period  when  the  law  was  enacted.  It  was  evi- 
dent that  most  of  the  applications  for  loans  would  come  from 
landowners  already  burdened  with  debt,  and  if  they  had  been 
deprived  of  credit,  the  legislation  would-  have  failed  of  its 
aim,  which  was  to  relieve  the  farmers  from  oppression  and 
usurious  practices  and  to  convert  their  heavy  existing  indebt- 
edness, bearing  excessive  interest,  into  easy  annuity  contracts, 
and  so  enable  it  to  be  paid  off  gradually  out  of  the  yearly 
savings  from  the  products  of  the  soil. 

The  Credit  Foncier  may  lend  to  individuals  upon  property 
covered  by  life  estates  or  long  leases,  provided  their  value 
added  to  the  amount  of  the  loan  does  not  exceed  one-half  the 
value  of  the  property.  This  provision  was  introduced  because 
it  often  happens,  especially  in  the  cities,  that  real  estate 
offered  for  mortgage  is  thus  encumbered  to  an  extent  very 


120  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

small  compared  with  its  total  value,  and  to  refuse  a  loan  to 
the  life  tenant  would  place  the  company  in  conflict  with  cus- 
tomary methods  of  the  country.  Long-term  leases  in  Europe 
frequently  run  for  99  years,  or  three  lives.  The  rent  is  rea- 
sonable. The  obligation  of  the  lessee  is  to  make  all  necessary 
repairs  and  improvements,  and  finally  to  surrender  the  prem- 
ises in  as  good  condition  as  when  he  received  them,  less  ordi- 
nary wear  and  tear.  The  mortgage  given  is  upon  the  revenues 
of  the  property. 

The  amount  of  a  loan  made  by  the  Credit  Foncier  on  real 
estate  cannot  exceed  one-half  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  prop- 
erty. The  maximum  is  one-third  for  properties  liable  to 
easy  depreciation,  such  as  forests,  vineyards,  orchards,  nur- 
series and  the  like,  while  mills  and  factories  are  estimated 
only  upon  their  value  independent  of  their  industrial  pur- 
poses. The  property  mortgaged  also  must  have  a  steady  and 
certain  revenue.  This  does  not  mean  that  at  the  time  it  is 
offered  for  security  the  property  should  in  fact  be  yielding  a 
revenue  of  the  kind  required;  but  it  must  be  rentable  and 
capable  of  returning  money  in  a  regular  manner.  For  this 
reason  the  Credit  Foncier  does  not  lend  upon  theaters,  mines 
or  quarries.  No  limit  is  fixed  as  to  the  size  of  a  loan  which 
may  be  made  to  one  person  or  on  any  piece  of  land. 

There  are  other  classes  of  property  which  may  not  be  used 
for  security.  The  Credit  Foncier  does  not  lend  on  the  public 
domain  or  upon  lands  to  which  is  attached  a  title  of  honor. 
Moreover,  lands  held  in  entail  or  subject  to  servitudes,  rights 
and  charges  which  cannot  be  removed,  or  lands  of  which  the 
applicant  is  only  part  owner  or  holds  the  fee  without  the  right 
of  possession,  or  has  no  power  to  dispose  except  in  a  speci- 
fied way  or  upon  authority  of  other  persons,  may  not  be  taken 
for  security  unless  all  parties  interested  consent  to  the  mort- 
gage. The  company,  of  course,  cannot  do  business  with 
minors,  outlaws,  incompetent  or  missing  persons  except 
through  their  guardians  or  trustees,  or  usually  with  wives 
without  consent  of  their  husband^. 

Applications  for  loans  must  be  made  on  forms  furnished 
by  the  company,  and  must  set  forth  the  amount  and  length  of 


FEANCE:   THE    CREDIT   FONCIER  121 

the  credit  desired  and  the  name  of  the  applicant's  attorney. 
If  the  applicant  is  a  department,  mimicipality  or  corporation, 
authority  for  the  application  and  the  resolution  providing 
for  the  repayment  of  the  loan  must  be  attached.  If  the  ap- 
plicant is  an  individual,  the  location,  nature,  value,  revenues, 
and  taxes  of  the  real  estate  offered  in  security  must  be  shown 
and  papers  produced  to  prove  the  owner's  title,  civil  state 
and  capacity,  ajid  marriage  agreements  affecting  the  property. 
The  applications  may  be  filed  at  headquarters  or  in  any  of  the 
ofBces  of  the  company  throughout  the  country. 

After  the  value  of  the  property  and  the  capacity  of  the 
owner  have  been  passed  upon  by  the  field  agents,  the  board 
of  directors  determine  the  amount  of  the  loan  which  may  be 
granted  and  a  conditional  contract  is  signed.  This  contract 
contains  aU  the  terms  of  the  loan  and  binds  the  company  to 
pay  and  the  applicant  to  receive  the  amount  applied  for  if  the 
title  to  the  property  is  found  perfect.  It  is  filed  with  the 
public  recorder  and  prevents  the  applicant  from  transferring 
his  property  or  encumbering  it  until  the  deal  is  closed  or 
called  oS. 

The  Credit  Foncier  then  proceeds  to  avail  itself  of  the 
most  important  privilege  which  has  been  given  to  mortgage- 
bond  companies  in  France  imder  the  law  of  1852.  After  as- 
suring itself  that  the  title  is  clear  of  all  registered  claims, 
it  starts  a  procedure  which  brings  to  light  any  hidden  claims. 
This  is  called  the  "purge."  It  consists  of  a  short  notice  offi- 
cially published  calling  on  third  parties  to  show  their  rights. 
The  process  takes  only  three  weeks  and  costs  about  one 
doUar.  If  claims  are  presented  as  a  result  of  this  notice,  the 
company  may  at  its  discretion  oppose  them  and  call  on  the 
owner  to  pay  the  cost  of  the  suit,  or  cancel  the  registration 
of  the  conditional  contract  and  reject  the  application.  If 
claims  are  not  presented,  no  third  party  can  ever  afterwards 
contest  the  company's  lien,  while  the  loan  applied  for  must 
be  granted.  The  filing  of  the  conditional  contract  and  the 
completion  of  the  formalities  of  the  purge  constitute  the 
company's  mortgage.  The  purge  for  mortgages  is  nothing 
more  than  the  Torrens  system  which  was  subsequently  devised 


122  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

in  South  Australia  in  1857  for  the  registration  of  all  titles  to 
land.  With  other  persons  a  mortgage  must  be  inscribed  anew 
every  ten  years  to  keep  it  alive,  but  this  requisite  is  dis- 
pensed with  for  companies  licensed  under  the  law  of  1852 
during  the  entire  period  of  the  credit.  The  final  contract 
for  the  loan  is  signed  by  an  official  representative  of  the 
president  of  the  company  and  by  the  borrower,  and  it  is 
certified  by  the  attorney  of  the  latter.  All  the  costs  are 
borne  by  the  applicant,  even  if  the  loan  is  refused.  They 
average  about  3.5  per  cent  of  the  loan;  thus,  for  a  loan  of 
$2,000  the  costs  would  be  $70. 

If  the  loan  is  for  a  short  term,  the  borrower  contracts  to 
pay  the  interest  and  the  principal  or  instalments  thereon  at 
the  stipulated  times,  but  if  it  is  for  a  long  term  he  contracts 
to  pay  neither  interest  nor  principal.  He  agrees  to  pay  an 
annuity  in  cash  every  six  months  in  advance.  The  annuity 
must  not  exceed  the  revenue  of  the  mortgaged  property. 
This  clause  was  inserted  in  the  law  to  prevent  the  borrower 
from  obligating  himself  to  pay  more  than  he  could  obtain 
from  the  returns  of  the  soil.  The  annuity  does  not  include 
any  assessment  for  cost  of  business,  as  is  the  ease  with  the 
German  landsehafts.  Its  rate  of  the  annuity,  as  already 
shown,  is  computed  upon  the  amount  of  the  loan,  the  length 
of  the  credit  and  the  agreed  interest. 

The  rate  of  interest  on  money  loaned  must  not  exceed 
by  more  than  six-tenths  of  one  per  cent  the  rate  of  the  de- 
bentures by  ^hich  it  was  raised,  except  in  Algeria  and  Tunis. 
The  present  rate  of  the  Credit  Fonder  for  mortgages  in 
France  is  .4.30  per  cent.  At  this  rate  the  half-yearly  annuity 
necessary  to  pay  $1,000  in  30  years  is  $29.82218.  If  the 
period  were  lengthened  the  annuity  of  course  would  be 
smaller.  As  a  rule  a  very  long  term  is  taken,  since  the 
choice  of  periods  between  ten  and  75  years  is  left  to  the 
borrower. 

So  long  as  the  borrower  keeps  his  engagements  the  com- 
pany can  never  recall  the  loan.  The  borrower,  however,  may 
make  advance  payments  in  whole  or  in  part  for  a  small  in- 
demnity of  one-half  of  one  per  cent  of  the  amount.    For  all 


FEANCE:   THE   CEEDIT   FONCIEK  133 

payments  except  annuities  he  may  use  either  currency  or 
debentures  of  the  issue  of  his  loan.  Accordiag  to  the  law  the 
company  is  bound  to  receive  debentures  so  tendered  at  par,  no 
matter  what  their  market  quotation  may  be.  The  courts 
cannot  grant  a  debtor  of  the  Credit  Foncier  any  delay  in  the 
payment  of  annuities,  nor  can  such  payment  be  stopped  by 
any  legal  proceeding.  This  means  that  a  creditor  neither 
of  the  company  nor  of  its  borrowers  can  interfere  by  any 
process  of  law  with  these  payments. 

If  a  borrower  defaults  his  interest  or  annuity  the  Credit 
Foncier  may  obtain  an  order  of  court  putting  it  in  possession 
of  the  mortgaged  premises  15  days  after  notice.  Five  per  cent 
interest  is  charged  on  arrears.  During  this  sequestration  the 
company  receives  the  revenues  and  crops,  may  rent  or  farm 
the  land,  make  aU  necessary  improvements  and  repairs,  and 
do  anything  for  its  upkeep  as  an  owner.  The  receipts  are 
applied  to  the  payment  of  the  debt  and  expenses.  When  its 
claim  is  satisfied  the  company  must  render  an  account  to  the 
debtor,  turn  over  to  him  any  balance  which  remains  in  its 
hands,  and  surrender  possession  of  the  land. 

Should  the  arrears  be  not  collected  through  the  seques- 
tration, the  Credit  Foncier  may  apply  to  the  court  for  an 
order  of  expropriation.  This  procedure  requires  only  one 
month  and  may  be  taken  whenever  the  loan  may  be  called 
in.  The  breaches  of  the  contract  which  give  the  company 
this  right,  besides  an  uncollectible  annxiity  or  interest,  are  the 
bankruptcy  of  the  debtor,  failure  to  repair  damages,  and  fail- 
ure to  give  notice  to  the  company  within  one  month  of  any 
conveyances  he  may  have  made  affectmg  the  title  or  pos- 
session of  the  property  or  of  any  deterioration  resulting  from 
fires  or  other  causes. 

During  the  trial  of  the  case  the  company  may  take  pos- 
session and  levy  on  the  property  for  the  full  amount  of  its 
claim.  Should  there  be  a  dispute  over  facts  the  matter  is 
summarily  decided.  The  company's  books  and  records  pre- 
vail over  any  evidence  furnished  by  the  borrower.  No  appeal 
is  allowed.  After  a  few  formalities  and  the  usual  publica- 
tions, the  sale  is  held  and  quickly  confirmed,  transferring 


124  EUKAL    CEEDITS 

all  the  defendant's  rights  in  the  mortgaged  property  to  the 
purchaser. 

The  distinguishing  feature  of  a  land-credit  bank  is  the 
right  to  issue  bonds  or  debentures.  No  matter  whether  its 
form  of  organization  be  cooperative  or  corporate,  these  must 
be  the  chief  sources  of  fimds  for  its  operations.  They  are 
negotiated  only  after  the  loans  are  made,  and  through  them 
the  credit  value  is  separated  from  the  mortgaged  property, 
split  up  into  convenient  parts,  and  mobilized,  while  the  bank 
which  issues  them  becomes  the  guarantor-ia-chief  to  the  lend- 
ers for  the  return  of  the  money  by  which  the  loans  were 
made. 

From  December,  1856,  to  July  24,  1877,  except  for  an 
interval  between  May,  1869,  and  December,  1870,  the  Credit 
Foncier  employed  the  German  landschaft  method  and  made 
its  loans  in  debentures.  Now,  however,  it  makes  its  loans 
in  cash  only,  and  since  the  retirement  of  the  series  issued 
prior  to  1879,  the  company  has  stopped  receiving  debentures 
on  advance  payments  of  borrowers,  in  spite  of  the  law  and 
the  provisions  in  its  charter.  Debentures  are  issued  and  used 
now  only  for  raising  funds  for  carrying  on  the  company's 
operations. 

The  debentures  are  of  four  classes.  The  first  class  are  for 
long-term  mortgage  loans;  the  second  for  loans  to  depart- 
ments, municipalities,  public  corporations,  etc.;  the  third  are 
of  three-  or  five-year  maturity  for  short-term  mortgage  loans ; 
and  the  fourth,  guaranteed  by  the  treasury  department,  are 
for  drainage  projects.  No  debentures  of  the  fourth  class  are 
in  issue.  Those  of  the  first  class  are  called  land,  and  those 
of  the  second  communal,  debentures.  The  total  of  all  classes 
in  circulation  must  not  .exceed  20  times  the  capital  stock  of 
the  company.  Land  debentures  may  be  issued  in  denomina- 
tions as  small  as  $20. 

The  land  and  communal  debentures  may  be  made  payable 
to  bearer  or  to  a  person  denominated  thereiu.  They  may  be 
transferred  in  the  first  case  by  mere  delivery,  in  the  second 
case,  only  by  written  assignment  on  the  stub  of  the  book 
from  which  they  are  detached.     They  are  numerically  re- 


PEANCE:    THE    CEBDIT   FONCIEE  125 

corded,  and  must  be  stamped  with  the  company's  seal,  signed 
by  a  director,  and  vised  by  the  president.  The  interest  is 
payable  half-yearly,  and  the  date  fixed  for  the  payment  of 
the  annuities  on  the  loans  is  fixed  at  least  three  months 
in  advance  of  the  interest  date  on  the  debentures.  This  gives 
ample  time  to  make  recovery  against  debtors  in  default. 

The  debentures  are  issued  in  large  blocks  or  series.  The 
smallest  existing  series  is  of  $50,000,000,  and  the  largest  of 
$180,000,000,  Although  the  company  thus  raises  its  operat- 
ing funds  in  advance,  however,  the  face  value  of  debentures 
in  circulation  must  never  exceed  the  amount  of  the  outstand- 
ing loans.  This  means  that  there  must  be  a  countervalue  of 
mortgages  or  loan  contracts  for  each  and  every  debenture 
sold.  Money  realized  from  the  sale  of  debentures  may  be  used 
for  no  other  purpose  than  making  loans.  Pending  its  em- 
ployment for  this  purpose  it  must  be  invested  in  govern- 
ment bonds  or  other  safe  securities. 

The  land  debentures  have  no  fixed  date  for  maturity. 
They  are  retired  by  drawing  lots  every  six  months.  At  each 
drawing  enough  debentures  must  be  called  in  so  that  those 
left  in  circulation  shall  not  exceed  in  face  value  the  total 
amount  of  loans  outstanding.  Debentures  withdrawn  by  lot 
cease  to  draw  interest.  Their  principal  becomes  due  after 
the  notice  that  they  have  been  drawn  for  redemption  is  duly 
published  in  the  newspapers  and  posted  at  headquarters. 
They  then  must  be  cancelled  and  destroyed.  Debentures  pur- 
chased by  the  company,  however,  may  be  returned  to  circu- 
lation upon  a  new  vise  by  the  president. 

With  the  consent  of  the  Government  the  Credit  Foncier 
may  issue  its  debentures  with  premiums  or  prizes.  Prizes 
are  given  in  all  but  one  of  the  13  issues  which  now  have 
debentures  in  circulation.  In  some  of  them  debentures  drawn 
for  retirement  may  receive  not  their  face  value  of  $30,  $50 
or  $100,  but  $200,  $1,000,  $2,000,  $5,000,  $10,000,  $20,000 
and  even  $40,000.  In  1911  there  were  4,362  chances  out- 
standing amounting  to  $2,842,000.  A  drawing  in  one  or 
more  of  the  issues  is  held  every  month  at  headquarters.  It 
is  plain  lottery  and,  as  the  management  says,  creates  quite 


136  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

an  attraction  for  the  debentures.     The  company's  pamphlet 
reads  in  translation  as  foUows: 

On  the  day  of  the  drawing  the  wheel  is  brought  forth  from 
its  iron  clad  and  guarded  vault.  In  presence  of  the  public  and 
the  auditors,  the  president  of  the  Credit  Foncier  surrounded 
by  the  board  of  directors  opens  the  session.  The  wheel  is  re- 
volved many  times  so  that  the  numbers  may  be  thoroughly 
mixed.  The  seals  are  then  examined  and  broken.  The  slot  is 
unlocked  and  opened,  and  a  child  from  a  public  orphan  asylum 
with  naked  arm  plunges  its  hand  into  the  wheel  and  draws  out 
a  number  which  the  president  immediately  reads,  and  thus 
makes  known  to  the  anxious  public  the  debenture  winning  the 
prize. 

Lottery,  however,  is  a  common  practice  in  France.  The 
bonds  of  the  city  of  Paris  and  of  many  other  public  and 
private  corporations  are  payable  with  prizes.  The  absence 
of  this  feature  would  probably  lower  the  price  of  the  deben- 
tures of  the  Credit  Foncier  but  it  is  difficidt  to  determine  the 
effect  of  its  presence  on  account  of  the  other  opportunities 
open  to  the  public  to  invest  in  bonds  having  similar  attrac- 
tions. Sir  Frederick  A.  Nicholson  contends  that  this  lottery 
is  not  a  gamble,  because  the  company  stands  no  chance  of 
winning  and  the  bondholders  no  risk  of  losing,  since  the 
debentures  must  always  be  paid  at  par  and  the  prize  or 
premium  is  calculated  as  a  part  of  the  cost  of  the  money 
raised  by  their  issue. 

Other  special  privileges  attach  to  the  debentures  of  the 
Credit  Foncier.  They  cannot  be  seized  by  any  legal  process, 
nor  may  any  suit  be  brought  to  stop  the  payment  of  their 
principal  or  interest  except  when  they  have  been  lost.  The 
company  is  not  responsible  for  the  regularity  of  endorse- 
ments on  debentures  and  is  legally  discharged,  as  in  the  case 
of  dividends  on  shares,  by  a  payment  of  the  interest  to  the 
holder  who  presents  them.  They  may  be  used  as  collateral 
by  the  Bank  of  France,  or  as  investment  for  funds  held 
in  trust  for  non-competents  and  of  municipalities,  pub- 
lic institutions  and  corporations  of  public  utility,  in   aU 


FEANCE:   THE   CKEDIT   FONCIEE  127 

eases  where  these  establishments  are  authorized  to  invest  their 
funds  in  government  bonds.  Moreover,  the  courts  have  de- 
cided that  they  may  be  used  also  for  the  investment  of  all 
funds  which  are  intended  by  agreement  or  understanding 
to  be  placed  in  real-estate  mortgages.  The  debentures  are 
free  from  the  stamp  tax,  the  company  being  subject  in  lieu 
thereof  to  a  small  annual  tax  upon  its  issues.  The  interest 
rates  are  determined  by  the  board  of  directors.  Debentures 
may  be  issued  below  par  but  must  be  redeemed  at  least 
at  par. 

The  Credit  Foncier  may  use  the  internal  revenue  ofBees 
for  making  its  remittances  to  holders  of  debentures  and  for 
receiving  the  dues  of  its  borrowers.  It  may  also  deposit  its 
funds  in  the  national  treasury  and  keep  a  current  account 
there.  Monthly  and  yearly  reports  must  be  submitted  to  the 
Minister  of  Finance  on  forms  prepared  by  that  office. 


CHAPTEE   XIII 

mANCE:   LAND   CEBDIT   FOE   AGEICTJLTUEE 

Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  de  Batiment. — Subsidiary  Company 
to  Credit  Fonder. — Operations  and  Management. — ^Applications 
for  Credit. — Long-term  Credit. — Statistics  of  Operations. — Not 
the  Intended  Aid  to  Agriculture. — Reason  in  Its  Centralization. 
— Central  Bank  for  Agricultural  Loans. — ^Long-term  Loans  to 
Associations  through  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel. — ^Long-term  Loans 
to  Individuals. — Two  Methods  of  Amortization. 

MtrcH  private  property  was  damaged  or  destroyed  in 
Paris  during  the  revolution  of  1848,  preceding  the  establish- 
ment of  the  Second  Eepublic.  The  Government  decided  to 
help  those  who  had  been  afflicted  the  most  by  public  dis- 
orders. To  this  end  it  assisted  in  founding  the  building  and 
loan  company  called  the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  de 
Batiment. 

At  first  the  notes  of  the  borrowers  of  this  company  were 
endorsed  over  to  a  bank  called  the  Comptoir  National  d'Es- 
compte,  which  was  authorized  to  discount  notes  with  only  two 
signatures.  Such  paper  is  not  bankable  ia  France  unless 
especially  authorized  by  law.  In  1860  the  Credit  Foncier  was 
authorized  to  discount  this  paper  and  was  substituted  for 
this  purpose  for  the  Comptoir  National.  A  contract  made 
with  the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  was  approved  by 
law.  Now  the  latter  concern  is  practically  a  subsidiary  of 
the  Credit  Foneier ;  its  capital  stock  is  $1,000,000,  and  three- 
fourths  of  it  is  deposited  as  a  guaranty  fund  with  the  Credit 
Foneier  upon  interest  equal  to  the  average  rate  of  discount  on 
its  notes. 

The  operations  of  this  company  cover  everything  relating 
to  the  building  business  and  public  works,  and  its  function 

128 


FEANCE:  LAND  CEEDIT  FOE  AGEICULTUEB    129 

is  to  procure  for  contractors,  traders,  and  laborers  therein, 
whether  they  be  principals,  sureties,  or  endorsers,  the  dis- 
counting of  their  negotiable  paper,  guaranteed  by  the  suffi- 
cient number  of  signers  or  secured  by  real  estate  or  pledges 
of  personal  property;  but  it  can  enter  into  no  operation 
without  the  consent  of  the  Credit  Fonder,  and  so  has  no 
control  over  the  remaining  one-fourth  of  its  capital  stock  and 
reserves,  while  its  inactive  funds  are  kept  on  account  cur- 
rent with  the  latter  company. 

The  manager  of  the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  is 
appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Finance.  The  by-laws  adopted 
with  the  approval  of  the  Government  cannot  be  changed  with- 
out its  consent.  The  president  and  vice-presidents  of  the 
Credit  Foncier  may  attend  the  meetings  of  its  board  of  direc- 
tors and  of  the  general  assembly  of  stockholders. 

The  limit  of  credit  is  fixed  by  the  Credit  Foncier  and 
can  never  exceed  twice  the  value  of  the  issued  shares  of  the 
Credit  Foncier  and  the  sub-company's  own  capital  stock. 
The  Credit  Foncier  undertakes  to  supply  the  Sous-Comptoir 
des  Entrepreneurs  with  the  necessary  funds  to  carry  on  its 
business. 

Every  application  for  credit  addressed  to  the  Sous-Comp- 
toir des  Entrepreneurs  is  submitted  to  its  board  of  directors. 
If  favorably  considered  the  board  appoints  a  commission  from 
among  its  members  to  make  a  report,  upon  which  it  deter- 
mines the  amount  and  length  of  the  credit  as  well  as  all 
other  conditions  of  the  loan.  If  the  applicant  agrees  to  the 
terms  and  furnishes  the  guaranties  required,  his  application, 
papers  and  plans,  together  with  the  report  of  the  commis- 
sion and  the  resolution  of  the  board,  are  delivered  to  the 
Credit  Foncier,  which  in  its  turn  approves  or  rejects  the  ap- 
plication. If  it  is  approved,  the  Credit  Foncier  draws  up  a 
contract  which  is  signed  by  the  applicant  and  a  director  of 
the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs.  The  only  part  of  its 
business  to  which  the  Credit  Foncier  extends  its  assistance 
is  that  connected  with  building  operations  and  public  works. 

When  any  particular  enterprise  is  accepted,  the  Sous- 
Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  selects  an  architect  to  watch  over 


130  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  work  and  to  certify  the  progress  made  by  the  owner. 
Three  days  before  each  pajrment  of  the  loan  is  due  the  bor- 
rower signs  a  note  to  its  order  payable  ia  three  months, 
which  is  endorsed  by  a  director  over  to  the  Credit  Foncier. 
Two  days  thereafter  the  amount  called  for  by  the  note,  less 
the  interest  at  the  rate  then  allowed  by  the  Credit  Foncier  for 
mortgages,  is  given  to  the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs. 
Eenewals  are  made  from  time  to  time  at  the  same  disQount 
rate  during  the  whole  period  agreed  upon  in  the  contract. 

After  the  completion  of  the  building,  if  the  owner  needs 
further  credit  he  may  obtain  a  long-term  loan  on  mortgage. 
In  this  way,  through  its  connection  with  the  Sous-Comptoir 
des  Entrepreneurs,  the  Credit  Foncier  may  extend  credit  to 
individuals  without  mortgage  security,  and  also  assist  owners 
to  build  on  unimproved  lands,  in  spite  of  the  provision  of 
the  law  which  forbids  it  to  lend  on  property  not  having  a 
durable  and  certain  revenue. 

In  1911  when  its  capital  stock  was  not  yet  increased  to 
its  present  figure  and  stood  at  $40,000,000,  the  Credit  Foncier 
had  outstanding  $461,060,057  of  mortgage  and  $409,357,156 
of  communal  loans,  or  a  total  of  $870,417,213.  The  deben- 
tures in  circulation  against  these  securities  amounted  to 
$785,639,948.  The  rate  of  interest  for  land  loans  was  4.30 
per  cent,  for  public  establishments  4.10  per  cent,  and  for  de- 
partments and  municipalities  3.85  per  cent  a  year.  One  of 
the  issues  of  land  debentures  yielded  2.80  per  cent,  another 
of  land  and  several  issues  of  communal  debentures,  2.60  per 
cent ;  and  the  rest  of  the  issues  3  per  cent  a  year.  The  sums 
coming  from  mortgage  and  communal  loans  were  $2,986,976, 
making  the  total  receipts  from  all  sources  $6,436,429.  De- 
ductions and  expenses  left  a  net  profit  of  $2,654,476,  out  of 
which  was  paid  a  dividend  of  6.40  per  cent  on  the  capital 
stock. 

The  deposits  and  current  accoimts  on  hand  were  $16,762,- 
173.  The  outstanding  loans  to  the  Sous-Comptoir  des 
Entrepreneurs  amounted  to  $22,783,500,  and  in  Algeria  and 
Tunis  to  $24,602,911.  Over  one  half  of  the  mortgage  loans 
made  by  the  Credit  Foncier  since  its  foundation  have  been 


PEANCE:  LAND  CEEDIT  FOE  AGEICULTFEE    131 

on  property  in  the  city  and  suburbs  of  Paris.  Loans  between 
$3,000  and  $10,000  are  the  most  numerous;  next  to  them 
are  the  loans  of  $1,000  and  under.  As  to  length  the  most 
numerous  loans  are  those  of  60  and  75  years;  next  to  them 
are  the  loans  of  21  to  30  years.  An  average  of  twenty-two 
and  a  fraction  loans  are  made  ia  the  cities  to  one  in  the 
country,  which  has  received  only  one-fourth  of  the  funds  of 
the  company  used  for  mortgages.  The  doubtful  claims  on 
hand  amounted  to  $372,048,  and  the  total  value  of  proper- 
ties acquired  in  foreclosure  and  not  yet  disposed  of  was 
$1,848,807. 

In  1913  the  market  price  of  the  3.5  per  cent  debentures 
was  97.4  per  cent,  and  of  the  3  per  cent  debentures,  90.6  per 
cent  of  their  face  value.  Shares  usually  are  sold  at  a  price 
to  net  the  purchaser  between  three  and  four  per  cent  on  his 
investment. 

Originally  the  Credit  Foncier  was  authorized  to  lend  only 
on  real-estate  mortgages  in  France.  Its  powers  to  make 
loans  without  mortgage  to  departments,  municipalities,  syndi- 
cal  associations,  hospitals  and  public  establishments,  and  in 
Algeria  and  Tunis,  were  added  by  successive  laws  and  de- 
crees, the  first  of  which  was  promulgated  eight  years  after 
its  foundation.  All  the  voluminous  literature,  official  rec- 
ords and  reports  relating  to  the  creation  of  this  great  land- 
credit  institution  show  that  the  chief  if  not  the  sole  purpose 
of  the  Government  in  bringing  it  into  existence  and  ia  vest- 
ing it  with  special  privileges  was  to  aid  agriculture.  Its 
founders  expressed  similar  intentions  in  a  most  emphatic  way 
but  the  figures  just  quoted  display  a  wide  discrepancy  be- 
tween promise  and  performance. 

The  fact  that  its  loans  on  urban  properties  and  to  munici- 
palities comprise  the  larger  part  of  its  operations  does  not 
signify,  however,  that  it  has  been  of  no  use  to  agriculture. 
It  is  stiU  the  greatest  single  factor  in  Prance  for  affording 
easy  credit  to  rural  landowners.  AU  persons  ovming  large 
or  medium-sized  farms  are  welcomed  by  the  Credit  Poncier, 
and  the  total  of  loans  to  agriculture  is  enormous.  But  the 
owners  of  small  holdings  are  utterly  ignored,  and  they  con- 


133  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

stitute  the  majority  whose  needs  and  resources  surpass  those 
of  all  others.  The  reasons  for  this  shortcoming  are  natural 
and  inherent.  The  Credit  Foneier  lacks'  proximity  to  the 
farmers,  without  which,  says  Sir  Frederick  A.  Nicholson, 
"there  is  no  such  thing  as  credit  on  any  reasonable  terms 
for  small  folk."     The  institution  is  highly  centralized. 

Decentralization  was  once  planned  for  it&  business  by 
establishing  local  boards  for  granting  loans  ia  all  the  depart- 
ments into  which  the  republic  is  diyided.  This  movement 
ended  in  opening  agencies  in  the  big  cities,  which  are  now 
used,  however,  mostly  for  selling  debentures  and  collecting 
dues.  Loans  continue  to  be  granted  only  upon  examiaation 
by  inspectors  and  appraisers  from  headquarters.  More  appli- 
cations are  presented  than  can  be  allowed.  Preference  is 
given  where  trouble  and  expense  may  be  saved,  so  the  bulk 
of  the  loans  go  to  the  cities. 

A  central  bank  was  created  in  1860  as  an  annex  to  the 
Credit  Foneier,  with  the  object  of  making  agricultural  loans 
throughout  the  country  for  short  terms  and  in  small  amounts 
on  personal  security.  It  did  not  succeed  because,  as  ex- 
plained by  the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  they  began  at  the 
top  and  crowned  the  edifice  before  building  a  firm  founda- 
tion of  groups  of  local  associations.  The  disastrous  failure 
of  this  bank,  the  causes  of  which  will  be  fully  explained  in 
another  chapter,  nearly  forced  the  parent  company  into  bank- 
ruptcy. Since  that  time  the  inability  of  the  Credit  Foneier 
to  render  extensive  service  to  small  farmers  has  been  so 
thoroughly  recognized  that  the  Government  has  never  con- 
sidered it  in  any  of  the  plans  proposed  and  adopted  by  the 
National  Assembly  for  improving  rural-credit  facilities. 

The  long-term  loans  provided  for  by  the  law  of  1906  are 
made  from  funds  obtained  by  the  state  from  the  Bank  of 
France  and  administered  through  a  system  of  rural  banks 
called  the  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  subject  to  the  general  con- 
trol of  the  Ministry  of  Agriculture.  This  system  and  its 
relation  to  the  Government  and  the  Bank  of  France  will  be 
described  hereafter.  The  total  of  the  collective  loans  each 
year  must  not  exceed  one-third  of  the  annual  payment  made 


FEANCE:  LAND   CEEDIT  FOE  AGEICULTUEE    133 

by  the  Bank  of  France  to  the  state,  and  they  can  be  made 
only  to  agricultural  cooperative  associations  organized  for  the 
production,  manufacturing  or  marketing  of  farm  products. 
In  the  chapter  describing  the  Credit  Agricole  it  will  be  found, 
however,  that  real  estate  security  is  not  always  required  for 
the  credit  accorded  to  the  cooperative  associations  under  the 
law  of  1906. 

Under  this  law  a  regional  bank  may  lend  to  such  an 
association  duly  afiBliated  with  a  local  bank  of  the  Credit 
Agricole  Mutuel  sums  repayable  within  25  years  provided 
they  be  used  for  the  purchase  of  real  estate,  for  erecting 
buildings,  or  for  installing  or  operating  machinery  therein. 
The  interest  is  two  per  cent  per  annum ;  for  a  loan  of  $1,000 
at  this  rate  to  be  amortized  iu  25  years,  the  annual  dues 
would  be  $51.22044.  No  association  may  receive  a  loan  unless 
it  is  composed  entirely  of  farmers  and  limits  the  maximum 
for  its  dividends  to  four  per  cent  a  year.  The  total  of  the 
loans  must  not  exceed  twice  its  paid-in  capital  stock. 

The  regional  bank  is  held  responsible  for  the  loan  and  for 
its  proper  use.  It  may  pay  over  the  money  only  as  the  work 
for  which  it  was  advanced  progresses.  If  the  loan  is  made 
for  the  purchase  or  improvement  of  land,  a  first  mortgage 
must  be  given  to  the  bank,  which  has  all  the  privileges  pro- 
vided by  the  law  of  1852  for  clearing  the  title  of  the  prop- 
erty and  for  recovering  its  claims. 

The  long-term  loans  to  individuals  provided  for  by  the 
law  of  1910  also  are  made  out  of  funds  obtained  from  the 
Bank  of  France  and  administered  through  the  Credit  Agricole 
Mutuel  and  land-credit  associations  organized  outside  of  this 
system,  conformably  to  a  law  of  1908. 

The  object  of  the  law  of  1908  is  to  aid  workers  to  ac- 
quire small  habitations  or  garden  plots  of  less  than  2.41 
acres.  The  law  of  1910  was  enacted  as  a  state  measure  prac- 
tically in  supplement  to  the  laws  making  military  service 
obligatory.  All  the  able-bodied  male  population  of  France 
must  serve  a  military  term  of  three  years.  Over  200,000 
yoimg  men,  having  completed  their  terms,  are  annually 
dropped  from  the  ranks,  many  with  inclinations  to  live  in 


134  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

cities  or  with  habits  of  wandering,  contracted  during  their 
service  in  the  Army  or  Navy.  The  spirit  of  the  law  of  1910 
is  to  assist  young  men  wishing  to  become  farmers  to  buy  or 
improve  small  homesteads  or  clear  them  of  encumbrances 
with  the  aid  of  the  state. 

Two-thirds  of  the  funds  coming  to  the  state  from  the 
Bank  of  France  may  be  used  for  these  long-term  loans  to 
individuals.  The  state  does  not  deal  directly  with  individ- 
uals. It  advances  the  money  to  the  land-credit  associations 
and  to  the  regional  banks,  as  intermediaries  of  the  local 
banks,  in  the  form  of  loans  for  20  years  without  interest  up 
to  twice  the  amount  of  their  capital  stock.  These  concerns 
may  employ  the  money  only  for  the  purpose  for  which  it  is 
intended. 

A  loan  made  by  a  local  bank  to  a  member  must  not  exceed 
$1,600  in  amount  or  15  years  in  duration.  The  interest  must 
be  at  least  two  per  cent  a  year,  which  is  the  rate  at  present. 
Two  systems  of  amortization  are  allowed.  In  one  the  bor- 
rower repays  the  loan  by  annuities,  in  the  other  by  instal- 
ments. Security  is  always  required.  If  the  borrower  uses 
the  loan  to  buy  property  he  must  give  a  first  mortgage 
thereon.  The  banks  have  the  privilege  of  the  "purge"  speci- 
fied in  the  law  of  1852  to  clear  the  title.  If  the  property  is  of 
such  a  nature  that  it  cannot  be  mortgaged,  that  is,  if  the 
applicant  formally  declares  it  to  be  his  homestead  exempted 
from  seizure  for  his  debts,  the  bank  must  insist  upon  the 
endorsement  of  responsible  persons  or  an  insurance  policy 
on  the  life  of  the  borrower  to  protect  its  claims.  By  1913 
close  to  $3,400,000  had  been  distributed  by  the  state  in  these 
long-term  loans  for  creating  small  rural  homesteads. 

Besides  assisting  farmers  to  acquire  small  homesteads, 
Prance  has  appropriated  $19,300,000  to  be  lent  to  laborers 
for  building  cheap  urban  dwellings.  The  distribution  of  this 
appropriation  is  intrusted  to  an  institution  called  the  Societe 
Credit  Immobilier,  or  Eeal  Estate  Credit  Company.  This 
company  pays  the  state  2  per  cent  and  charges  borrowers 
between  2  and  3  per  cent,  the  difference  being  used  to  cover 
expenses.     At  present  the  rates  are  3  per  cent  for  laborers 


FEANCE:  LAND  CEEDIT  FOE  AGEICULTUEE    135 

with  two  children,  3%  per  cent  for  laborers  with  three  chil- 
dren, 3^  per  cent  for  laborers  with  four  children,  and  214 
per  cent  for  laborers  with  five  children.  The  Soeiete  Credit 
ImmobUier  will  advance  only  fonr-fifths  of  the  amount  neces- 
sary to  build  the  dwelling,  and  it  requires  all  dweUiags  to 
be  constructed  upon  lands  and  plans  approved  by  its  board 
of  directors.  The  liens,  which  must  always  be  secured  by 
mortgage,  may  be  repaid  by  annuities  running  30  to  30  years. 


CHAPTEK   XIV 

ITALY 

Present  Institutions. — ^History  of  Land  Credit. — ^Failures  Due  tO' 
Overlooking  Farmers'  Interests. — Istituto  ItaJiano  di  Credito 
Fondiario  of  1891. — Banks  of  Issue. — ^Present  Savings  Banks. — 
Land-credit  Business  Kept  Separate. — ^Loan  Security. — Interest. 
— Debentures. — Payments. — Capital  Stock  of  Istituto  Italiano. — 
Powers  of  Company. — Emphyteusis. — ^Agricultural  Credit  Given 
by  Savings,  Commercial  and  Cooperative  Banks,  the  Monti  Pru- 
mentarii,  and  Associations  of  Land  Owners. 

The  campaign  for  organizing  land-credit  in  Italy  was 
started  over  half  a  century  ago  and  it  has  not  ended  yet. 
The  history  of  land  credit  in  Italy  is  the  worst  of  any  Euro- 
pean country  and  shows  how  easily  hasty  and  defective  legis- 
lation may  lead  to  an  inflation  and  collapse  of  credit.  Eight 
laws  were  passed  and  16  royal  decrees  promulgated  within 
the  first  20  years  of  the  campaign.  These  enactments  were 
inspired  by  the  needs  of  agriculture  but  framed  to  include 
both  the  town  and  country.  The  last  of  them  was  placed  on 
the  statute  book  about  the  time  when  the  larger  Italian  cities 
began  to  boom,  and  the  new  credit  facilities  were  recklessly 
utilized  in  the  wild  craze  which  ensued  to  finance  building 
projects,  to  the  exclusion  of  rural  betterment.  The  Govern- 
ment encouraged  this  boom  for  five  years  and  then,  reversing 
its  course,  set  on  foot  investigations  and  strove  to  stem 
the  tide,  but  too  late  to  avert  disaster.  The  state  finally 
had  to  intervene  to  protect  bondholders  from  the  losses 
incurred  through  bad  loans  made  by  most  of  the  banks 
which  the  state  had  empowered  to  do  a  land-credit  busi- 
ness, and  many  years  were  required  to  straighten  out  this 
trouble. 

The  Italian  system  at  present  comprises  a  nxunber  of 
136 


ITALY  137 

benevolent  or  non-profit  making  institutions  and  one  com- 
pany, created  by  special  acts  or  royal  decrees  but  all  operat- 
ing under  general  laws.  There  is  neither  monopoly,  special 
privilege  nor  state  aid  now,  and  in  the  free  competition  allowed 
interest  rates  have  been  so  reduced  that  borrowers  obtain 
money  on  as  easy  terms  as  landowners  in  any  other  nation. 
These  institutions  do  not  cover  aU  Italy  equally.  They 
have  not  yet  supplied  the  islands  and  the  southern  part  of 
the  coimtry  with  adequate  credit  facilities,  but  year  by  year 
they  have  absorbed  a  larger  proportion  of  the  land  indebted- 
ness and  they  are  able  to  extend  their  operations  as  rapidly 
as  the  intelligence  and  material  needs  of  the  farming  class 
advance  and  develop. 

In  1861,  after  various  projects  had  been  formulated  and 
one  launched  without  success,  the  Italian  Government  ap- 
pointed a  commission  to  study  land  credit.  The  commission 
advised  that  a  company  be  established  along  French  lines, 
with  a  state  subsidy  and  a  board  of  directors  composed  of 
nine  Italian  citizens  and  eight  Frenchmen  under  a  high 
ofiBcer  of  the  Credit  Foncier  of  France.  This  recommenda- 
tion was  rejected.  A  second  plan  was  presented  on  October 
4,  1865,  dividing  Italy  into  northern,  central  and  southern 
zones,  and  proposing  a  monopoly  to  an  existing  savings  bank 
in  each  zone.  But  on  November  21  of  the  same  year  a  third 
plan,  based  on  an  agreement  between  the  Government  and 
five  savings  banks,  was  adopted,  and  in  accordance  therewith 
Italy  enacted  her  first  land-credit  law  in  1866. 

The  law  gave  to  each  of  these  five  institutions  the  exclusive 
right  to  issue  debentures  against  real-estate  mortgages  and 
loans  to  municipalities  within  its  specified  territory.  In 
1870,  1872,  and  1873,  three  other  savings  banks  were  given 
the  same  right  for  their  respective  territories.  The  arrange- 
ment, however,  was  unsatisfactory.  By  the  end  of  1880  the 
banks  had  lent  only  $48,354,994  of  the  $1,302,480,000  of 
interest-bearing  indebtedness  which  encumbered  the  land  in 
Italy,  although  a  law  of  1873  had  authorized  the  king  to  com- 
pel them  to  open  branches  so  as  to  get  in  closer  touch  with 
landowners. 


138  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

In  1881  these  institutions  held  a  conference  the  object 
of  which  was  to  have  their  territorial  limits  removed.  This 
was  accomplished  in  1885  by  the  second  law  of  importance 
respecting  land  credit  in  Italy.  The  law  allowed  the  banks 
to  operate  throughout  the  kingdom  but  took  away  their  mo- 
nopolies. It  authorized  the  organization  or  license  of  other 
banks  provided  each  had  a  capital  stock  of  $3,000^000.  Later 
on  licenses  were  given  to  the  Bank  of  the  Tiber  and  the 
Bank  of  Italy.  Associations  of  borrowers  were  also  author- 
ized, prowded  the  properties  of  the  members  were  worth 
$1,000,000  and  only  half  of  this  was  used  as  cover  for  deben- 
tures. No  association  of  borrowers,  however,  came  into  exist- 
ence until  1911.  In  that  year  about  300  Sicilians  formed  the 
Landowners'  Mutual  Association  to  operate  throughout  the 
kingdom. 

Other  laws  in  1885  authorized  the  banks  to  finance  sani- 
tation projects  in  cholera-stricken  Naples,  and  in  1887  to 
make  loans  in  several  provinces  to  restore  buildings  dam- 
aged by  earthquakes.  The  Government,  in  fact,  seemed  to 
consider  that  the  chief  object  of  these  banks  should  be  to 
extend  help  to  large  enterprises  and  to  property  owners  in  the 
cities,  and  it  was  bitterly  accused  of  encouraging  them  in  that 
direction.  By  this  time  their  business  had  reached  enormous 
proportions  but  the  service  rendered  farmers  and  small  land- 
owners was  insignificant.  The  average  size  of  aU  loans  was 
over  $10,000,  and  a  large  portion  of  them  were  in  Eome,  where 
the  boom  had  been  most  active.  The  excuse  for  ignoring 
the  farmers  was  that  the  banks  found  that  they  could  not 
accord  credit  away  from  their  immediate  vicinities  except  in 
the  capital  city. 

In  1887  one  of  the  banks  failed.  By  1889  the  price  of 
debentures  began  to  fall,  owing  to  excessive  issues  and  public 
distrust.  An  effort  to  create  an  outside  market  for  them  in 
France  proved  futile.  No  more  money  could  be  raised  and 
the  boom  burst.  Defaults  in  loans  became  frequent  and  the 
arrears  of  borrowers  and  imsalable  properties  taken  in  fore- 
closure tied  up  the  funds  of  the  banks.  The  Government 
then  realized  that  something  was  wrong  with  the  system. 


ITALY  139 

The  chief  mistakes  were  that  the  farmers'  interests  had 
been  overlooked,  and  that  the  banks  had  involved  themselves 
too  heavily  in  building  operations  in  the  large  cities  and 
had  let  their  real-estate  transactions  become  badly  mixed  with 
their  banking  business.  In  1890  the  Government,  returning 
to  the  original  idea,  provided  by  its  third  important  law  for 
the  creation  of  the  Istituto  Italiano  di  Credito  Pondiario,  a 
bond  and  mortgage  company  similar  to  the  Credit  Foncier 
of  France.  When  this  company  was  chartered  in  1891,  aU 
other  banks  were  compelled  to  withdraw  into  their  original 
territories,  except  two  which  were  allowed  to  continue  opera- 
tion in  Rome.  The  intention  was  to  have  the  Istituto  handle 
the  loans  in  the  cities  and  those  of  large  landowners  and  to 
require  the  savings  banks  to  devote  their  attention  to  small 
farmers  in  their  respective  neighborhoods.  A  commission  was 
appointed  to  investigate  the  causes  and  extent  of  the  trou- 
bles which  had  arisen. 

In  1893  another  bank  failed.  In  the  same  year  the  mort- 
gage laws  were  reformed  by  the  fourth  law  of  importance  and 
the  three  banks  of  issue  which  had  been  acting  as  land  banks 
were  ordered  to  close  up  their  land-credit  business.  The 
disappearance  of  these  four  banks  left  large  areas  of  Italy 
without  land-credit  facilities.  Hence,  on  August  5,  1895, 
the  law  of  1885  was  amended  to  allow  land-credit  compa- 
nies to  be  organized  with  only  $400,000  of  capital.  This 
amendment  brought  no  results,  and  in  November  aU  existing 
banks  were  empowered  to  make  loans  in  the  areas  abandoned 
by  the  four  banks  just  mentioned. 

In  1896  by  another  law  territorial  restrictions  were  com- 
pletely removed,  and  aU  banks  duly  licensed  were  again  al- 
lowed to  operate  throughout  the  kingdom.  Banks  of  issue, 
however,  were  forbidden  forever  to  extend  land  credit.  The 
investigation  showed  that  those  which  had  done  so  did  not 
properly  segregate  their  real-estate  transactions  from  their 
banking  business,  and  that  they  had  frequently  entered  into 
agreements  with  building  contractors,  discounted  their  notes 
or  given  them  drawing  accounts,  with  the  object  of  sharing 
in  the  profits  and  in  the  hope  of  strengthening  the  security 


140  EURAL   CREDITS 

for  their  loans  when  the  building  operations  they  had  thus 
financed  were  finished. 

The  six  banks  of  issue  in  Italy,  of  which  three  had  been 
licensed  to  grant  land  credit,  had  immobilized  $59,940,000 
of  their  assets  within  the  comparatively  short  period  of  their 
operations.  They  committed  the  errors  which  the  Credit 
Foncier  of  France  avoided  through  its  connections  with  a 
subsidiary  company,  the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs  de 
Bitiment.  To  save  the  country  from  the  consequences  of 
these  errors  the  state  had  to  guarantee  the  payment  of  the 
debentures  of  one  of  the  largest  banks,  on  terms,  however, 
which  the  holders  were  forced  to  accept. 

These  laws  were  codified  in  1905.  At  present  there  are 
five  savings  banks,  one  company  connected  with  a  savings 
bank,  one  landowners'  association,  androne  joint-stock  com- 
pany operating  under  this  code,  while  all  institutions  or 
societies  authorized  to  issue  debentures  against  real-estate 
loans  are  subject  to  its  provisions  and  amendments  unless 
specially  excepted.  These  savings  banks,  which  are  very  old, 
were  created  for  some  object  of  charity  or  public  utility  by 
funds  donated  by  the  Government  or  by  philanthropists. 
Their  original  purpose  and  spirit  have  been  maintained,  and 
any  profits  gained  are  used  to  increase  these  funds  or  re- 
serves. Four  of  them  make  loans  throughout  the  kingdom. 
The  fifth  restricts  itself  to  the  province  in  which  it  is  located. 

The  oldest  of  these  benevolent  institutions  is  in  Siena.  In 
1500  Siena,  then  a  republic,  granted  to  some  Jewish  capi- 
talists, their  heirs  and  assigns,  the  right  to  make  loans  on 
pledge  or  mortgage  throughout  its  territory.  The  conces- 
sion was  misused,  so  in  1569  an  old  charitable  establishment 
founded  in  1471  was  revived  by  the  Government  to  combat 
the  Jews.  This  concern  did  not  bring  the  expected  relief 
because  it  confined  its  business  entirely  to  taking  pledges. 
Thereafter  a  special  mortgage  bank  was  created  by  the  Gov- 
ernment with  a  capital  composed  of  shares  of  one  hundred 
scudi  ($93).  The  capital  not  being  raised  by  private  sub- 
scription to  the  required  amount,  the  Grand  Duke  Ferdi- 
nand II  of  Tuscany  completely  reorganized  the  bank,  ad- 


ITALY  141 

vanced  to  it  200,000  scudi  on  the  guaranty  of  the  commune, 
and  renamed  it  Monte  dei  Paschi,  or  the  bank  for  the  pasture 
lands  of  Siena.  This  public  savings  bank  of  Siena  now  has 
many  branches  outside  of  that  locality,  and  besides  receiving 
the  deposits  of  the  poor,  extends  short-  and  long-time  credit 
in  small  and  large  amounts,  and  does  an  accident  insurance 
business  for  workmen. 

Following  this  bank  in  chronological  order  is  the  Pious 
Works  of  Saint  Paul  of  Turin,  created  by  the  absorption 
of  various  funds  and  the  consolidation  of  a  number  of  con- 
cerns of  a  charitable  nature,  some  of  which  were  established 
in  1562.  It  was  reorganized  by  royal  decree  in  1852,  and  its 
board  of  directors  is  now  composed  of  24  members,  one  half 
of  whom  are  appointed  by  the  city  of  Turin  and  one  half  by 
the  Minister  of  the  Interior.  The  board  manages  these  com- 
bined funds  but  keeps  a  separate  account  for  each. 

The  next  in  point  of  age  is  the  Savings  Bank  of  Milan, 
founded  in  1825  by  a  special  tax  levied  upon  real  estate  in 
Lombardy.  This  tax  was  collected  between  1815  and  1817 
to  aid  poor  people  who  had  suffered  from  a  drouth  which 
destroyed  the  crops  just  before  that  period.  The  unex- 
pended portion  was  turned  over  to  this  bank.  At  first  it  made 
only  mortgage  loans  but  now  does  all  kinds  of  commercial 
banking,  while  its  deposit  business  is  one  of  the  largest  in 
Italy. 

The  other  two  are  the  Savings  Bank  of  Bologna  and  the 
Savings  Bank  of  Verona.  The  former  has  a  joint-stock 
form  of  organization  but  its  stockholders  receive  no  dividends. 
The  latter  was  founded  in  1900  with  certain  endowment  funds 
for  the  Venetian  provinces  and  Mantua.  Besides  these  five 
institutions,  the  Land  Credit  Company  of  Sardinia  was  or- 
ganized as  a  corporation  in  1898  by  the  shareholders  of  the 
Savings  Bank  of  Cagliari. 

The  land-credit  business  of  these  charitable  and  public 
savings  banks  is  carried  on  in  special  sections  so  as  to  segre- 
gate it  from  all  other  affairs.  Each  section  generally  is  man- 
aged by  a  board  of  directors  and  a  committee  of  supervision 
composed  of  sis  members,  of  whom  one  is  an  officer  of  the 


143  EUEAL    CREDITS 

bank,  one  a  representative  of  the  provincial  council,  one  a 
representative  of  the  city  council  and  one  a  representative 
from  the  local  chamber  of  commerce.  The  other  two  are 
auditors  appointed  by  the  bank. 

Eeserves  are  compulsory.  If  the  bank  is  a  joint-stock 
company,  it  must  set  aside  one-fourth  of  its  net  annual  profits 
until  the  reserve  equals  at  least  one-fifth  of  the  paid-in 
capital.  If  it  has  no  capital  stock,  the  reserve  must  accumu- 
late until  it  reaches,  together  with  any  guaranty  fund,  one- 
tenth  of  its  debentures  in  circulation.  The  reserves  must  be 
invested  in  bonds  of  the  Government  or  of  other  land-credit 
institutions.  Supervision  is  exercised  by  the  Minister  of  Agri- 
culture, Industry  and  Commerce,  who  has  the  right  of  inspec- 
tion, and  the  authority  to  prescribe  rules  for  the  conduct  of 
business. 

Loans  of  the  savings  banks  must  be  secured  by  first  mort- 
gages on  real  property  worth  at  least  double  their  amount 
and  yielding  a  durable  and  certain  revenue.  The  restrictions 
regarding  the  kinds  of  property  allowed  for  security  are 
similar  to  those  in  the  French  law.  If  the  money  for  a 
loan  comes  out  of  the  capital  stock  or  funds  actually  belong- 
ing to  the  savings  banks,  the  loan  contract  may  provide  for 
repayment  in  lump.  If  it  comes  from  the  issue  and  sale  of 
debentures,  the  loan  must  be  made  repayable  only  by  annui- 
ties, unless  the  period  of  the  credit  is  imder  ten  years,  when 
it  may  be  made  repayable  in  yearly  or  half-yearly  instal- 
ments or  otherwise.    The  longest  period  allowed  is  50  years. 

The  interest  rate  on  a  loan  must  equal  that  of  the  deben- 
tures issued  against  it,  and  is  determined  by  the  bank.  In 
addition  to  the  interest,  annuity  or  instalment,  the  borrower 
may  be  required  to  pay  0.45  per  cent  of  the  principal  each  year 
for  the  expenses  of  business  and  a  further  0.15  or  0.10  per 
cent  as  a  government  tax,  together  with  all  costs  of  the 
loan.  The  interest  and  annuity  must  be  paid  in  cash.  The 
loan  may  be  prepaid  in  whole  or  in  part  and  debentures  used 
for  this  purpose,  but  the  contribution  towards  the  expense 
of  business  and  the  government  tax  continue  on  the  full 
amount  of  the  loan  until  its  complete  extinction. 


ITALY  143 

The  savings  bank  frequently  extend  credit  for  periods  of 
a  few  years  on  running  accounts  up  to  specified  amounts, 
in  a  way  that  requires  the  borrower  to  pay  interest  only  on 
the  balance  due  instead  of  upon  the  full  face  value  of  the 
mortgage  given  as  security.  Such  loans,  as  weU  as  loans  out 
of  the  banks'  own  funds,  may  be  made  in  cash,  but  in  all 
other  cases  the  bank  simply  exchanges  its  debentures  for  the 
borrower's  mortgage  and,  unless  it  does  the  selling  for  him, 
the  borrower  sells  them  himself  and  must  suffer  the  loss  if  the 
sale  be  at  less  than  par. 

The  denominations  of  these  debentures  are  $30  or  more, 
bearing  three  and  one-half,  four,  four  and  one-half  and  five 
per  cent  interest  per  annum  or  maximum  allowed,  and  maj 
be  made  payable  to  bearer  or  otherwise.  Interest  coupons 
are  always  paid  to  bearer.  The  debentures  of  each  rate  con- 
stitute a  separate  series  but  all  are  equally  secured  by  the 
mass  of  mortgages  taken  and  the  guaranty  funds  accumu- 
lated by  the  bank.  The  borrower  has  the  right  to  select  the 
series  he  wishes  for  his  loan  and  to  repay  it  in  debentures  of 
the  same  kind.  Debentures  are  recallable  at  the  wUl  of  the 
bank,  but  it  must  retire  semi-annually  by  lot  debentures  equal 
to  the  amount  of  the  cash  in  the  sinking  fund  or  due  to  it.. 

All  payments  on  the  principal  of  loans  and  the  proceeds 
from  foreclosure  sales  go  into  this  fund.  It  is  debited  with 
all  defaults  of  borrowers.  The  bank  must  supply  any  arrear- 
age from  its  own  funds  or  capital  stock.  Consequently  no 
dead  loans  can  be  used  as  cover  for  debentures.  Each  half- 
year  the  drawing  is  continued  until  the  total  face  value  of  the 
debentures  retired  equals  the  amount  of  the  items  under  these 
three  heads,  and  thus  an  exact  equilibrium  is  always  main- 
tained between  the  debentures  in  circidation  and  loans  out- 
standing. Beyond  this  regulation  no  limit  is  set  to  the 
amount  of  debentures  which  a  savings  bank  may  issue  against 
loans,  unless  it  be  a  joint-stock  company,  in  which  case  it  can- 
not be  in  excess  of  ten  times  the  capital  stock.  It  will  thus  be 
seen  that  the  method  of  operation  of  the  German  landschafts 
has  been  adopted  for  these  old  benevolent  Italian  savings 
banks ;  they  do  not  aim  to  make  a  profit  out  of  the  borrowers. 


144  EURAL   CEEDITS 

The  interest,  annuities  or  principal  of  loans  when  due  to 
a  bank  cannot  be  stayed  nor  delayed  by  any  legal  proceeding. 
Its  mortgages  do  not  have  to  be  refiled  every  20  years  to  keep 
"them  alive  as  under  the  civil  code.  The  public  recorder  must 
perform  this  service  for  it  free  of  cost  until  the  end  of  the 
credit  period.  The  bank  may  declare  all  the  principal  of  a 
loan  to  be  due  if  there  is  default  in  the  interest  or  annuity. 
It  may  recover  arrears  of  an  annuity  out  of  the  borrower's 
personal  property  by  the  same  process  employed  by  the  state 
ior  coUectiug  unpaid  taxes,  and  may  resort  to  summary  pro- 
ceedings for  foreclosure  and  sale.  Its  debentures  may  be 
Teceived  in  pledge  as  security  for  loans  up  to  four-fifths  their 
market  value  by  other  land-credit  banks,  or  by  any  credit 
•establishments  or  the  ITational  Bank  for  the  same  purpose  up 
"to  the  limit  prescribed  in  their  by-laws.  Moreover,  the  deben- 
"tures  are  lawful  investments  for  the  funds  of  cities,  prov- 
inces and  the  state,  and  of  charitable  institutions,  savings 
hanks,  and  public  loan  offices,  up  to  nine-tenths  of  their 
market  value.  They  are  exempt  from  levy  and  sale  on  exe- 
•cution.  They  are  also  free  from  taxes  on  personal  property 
vrhen  the  bank  charges  them  against  the  borrower.  This 
prevents  double  taxation. 

The  law  of  1890  under  which  the  Istituto  Italiano  di 
Credito  Fondiario  (Land  Credit  Company  of  Italy)  was 
■organized  in  1891  is  a  special  act.  Its  object  was  to  create 
■a  large  central  institution  by  stock  subscriptions  and  absorp- 
tion of  the  mortgage  business  of  the  then  existing  banks. 
For  this  purpose  it  was  granted  an  exclusive  monopoly  to 
-operate  throughout  the  kingdom  for  15  years,  while  the  banks, 
as  already  stated,  were  compelled  to  stop  making  loans  out- 
side their  respective  original  territories.  This  monopoly,  how- 
ever, was  taken  away  in  1894. 

The  capital  stock  of  this  company  is  $20,000,000,  of 
"which  $8,000,000  has  been  paid  in.  The  National  Bank  of 
Italy  contributed  $2,000,000  of  mortgages  and  $1,000,000 
in  cash  towards  its  foundation;  the  rest  was  subscribed  by 
Italian  citizens  and  foreigners.  The  capital  stock,  reserves 
-and  guaranty  fund  must  all  be  invested  in  mortgages.    Five 


ITALY  14& 

per  cent  of  the  net  profits  must  go  into  the  reserve  until  it 
equals  one-fiith  of  the  paid-in  capital;  from  the  remainder 
a  dividend  of  six  per  cent  may  be  declared  to  shareholders. 
One-fourth  of  the  balance  goes  to  the  state,  one-fourth  to 
the  reserve  until  it  reaches  the  statutory  amount,  and  the 
rest  is  disposed  of  as  the  shareholders  may  decide  at  the 
annual  meeting. 

The  sole  powers-  of  the  company  are  to  grant  land  credit 
and  to  issue  and  negotiate  debentures  to  finance  its  opera- 
tions up  to  ten  times  the  amount  of  its  paid-in  capital.  The 
loans  are  made  in  cash,  but  the  interest  rate  must  be  the 
same  as  that  of  the  debentures  which  were  issued  for  raising 
the  money  loaned.  The  debentures  are  issued  en  bloc  and 
not  as  each  loan  is  granted;  for  example,  after  the  company 
has  made  $1,000,000  of  loans  out  of  its  capital  stock,  it  may 
issue  debentures  for  that  amount.  The  profits  come  from 
commissions,  which  are  fixed  by  the  company  itself.  This 
right  is  allowed  all  land-credit  institutions  when  the  loan  is 
made  in  cash  and  not  in  debentures,  and  each  has  a  printed 
schedule  of  such  commissions.  The  Istituto  is  supervised  by 
the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  Commerce  and  Industry,  and 
enjoys  no  privileges  beyond  those  laid  down  in  the  general 
laws. 

The  lowest  rate  of  interest  on  loans  made  by  the  institu- 
tions forming  the  land-credit  system  is  about  4.41  per  cent. 
The  average  is  perhaps  5  per  cent,  after  taking  into  account 
all  costs,  charges,  and  losses  on  debentures  sold  below  par 
when  loans  are  made  in  debentures.  The  rate  is  tending  to 
increase,  however,  and  some  of  the  institutions  are  now 
issuing  debentures  only  at  the  highest  interest  rates  allowed 
and  are  calling  in  those  of  lower  rates.  This  is  due  to  the 
fact  that  money  is  becoming  dearer  in  Italy.  The  3.5  per 
cent  debentures  of  all  the  institutions  are  quoted  at  par 
and  are  as  acceptable  to  the  investiag  public  as  government 
bonds.  The  loans  are  usually  for  very  long  terms.  Most 
of  the  loans  of  the  Istituto  run  for  45  to  50  years.  The 
annuity  for  the  latter  period  is  6.10  per  cent.  A  fair  propor- 
tion of  the  business  of  all  the  institutions  is  rural.     They 


146  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

held  in  1912  $733,246,124  of  the  $1,302,480,451  of  existing 
interest-bearing  land  indebtedness  in  Italy. 

Much  of  the  land  ia  Italy  owned  in  large  tracts  by  private 
individuals  or  corporations  is  occupied  under  a  right  called 
■"emphyteusis."  This  is  a  grant  of  the  possession  and  use, 
subject  to  the  keeping  of  the  land  in  cultivation  and  from 
depreciation  and  to  the  payment  of  a  fixed  annual  rent  either 
in  cash  or  kind.  This  grant  or  lease  is  usually  for  a  very 
long  term  and  may  be  perpetual.  It  is  inheritable  and  may 
be  sublet  upon  certain  conditions,  but  the  occupants,  of 
course,  cannot  seU  or  mortgage  the  land.  There  are  hun- 
dreds of  thousands  of  such  occupants  besides  ordinary  tenants, 
and  they  are  unable  to  obtain  loans  from  the  land-credit  insti- 
tutions by  reason  of  this  lack  of  title. 

This  situation  was  remedied  by  the  law  of  1887,  which 
declared  that  growing  crops,  stored  produce,  live  stock,  im- 
plements and  buildings,  which  up  to  that  time  were  legally 
a  part  of  the  land,  should  be  considered  as  movable  fixtures 
to  the  extent  that  tenants  by  emphyteusis  or  ordinary  lease 
could  mortgage  them  for  certain  purposes  to  any  institution 
duly  authorized  to  accord  agricultural  credit.  The  mortgage 
thus  made  is  a  lien  on  the  property,  subject  to  the  land- 
lord's or  landowner's  right  to  the  rent  for  the  current  year 
and  the  two  years  before  and  the  one  thereafter.  If  the  land 
is  iQcreased  in  value  as  a  result  of  the  credit  extended,  the 
lien  has  precedence,  to  the  amount  of  the  increase,  over  all 
claims  of  the  landlord  or  mortgages  made  by  him  though 
prior  in  point  of  time.  The  lien  expires  unless  renewed  every 
three  years. 

The  institutions  which  may  be  authorized  to  accord  agri- 
cultural credit  are  savings,  commercial  and  cooperative  banks, 
the  Monti  Frumentarii  (public  granaries),  and  associations 
of  landowners  the  aggregate  value  of  whose  estates  is  $600,000 
or  over.  These  institutions  may  have  renewals  filed  and 
recorded  free  of  charge,  while  other  fees  of  the  recorders  and 
notaries  as  well  as  stamp  duties  are  reduced  on  their  busi- 
ness to  one-half  of  the  legal  rate.  They  also  may  resort  to 
the  special  processes  against  delinquent  borrowers  enjoyed 


ITALY  147 

by  land  banks.  These  privileges  are  allowed  and  the  tenants' 
mortgages  are  valid  only  vrhen  the  loans  are  made  for  build- 
ing farm  homes,  barns,  fences  and  storehouses,  for  drainage, 
irrigation  and  digging  weUs,  for  planting  vines  and  fruit 
trees,  for  dyking  and  opening  watercourses,  constructing 
roads  and  preparing  land  for  cultivation,  and  for  such  other 
objects  as  the  Agricultural  Council  of  the  nation  may  declare 
to  be  proper.  The  loans  must  be  made  in  cash  as  the  work 
for  which  they  were  obtained  progresses.  A  misuse  of  the 
money  renders  the  principal  due.  The  rate  of  interest  must 
not  exceed  a  maximum  fixed  by  the  Ministers  of  the  Treasury 
and  of  Agriculture,  Commerce  and  Industry.  The  term  can- 
not be  less  than  three  nor  more  than  30  years,  and  repay- 
ment must  be  by  instalments  or  annxiities. 

When  an  institution  has  been  duly  authorized  to  accord 
agricultural  credit,  it  may  do  business  with  small  landown- 
ers and  cooperative  societies  as  weU  as  with  tenants.  After 
it  has  employed  one  half  of  its  own  capital  or  fund  spe- 
cially set  aside  for  the  purpose  in  making  these  agricultural 
loans,  it  may  issue  debentures  to  raise  further  money  for 
carrying  on  its  operations.  The  face  value  of  the  debentures 
in  circulation  at  any  one  time  must  never  exceed  five  times 
its  capital  or  the  amount  of  the  outstanding  loans.  The 
debentures  are  of  two  kinds,  printed  in  different  colors.  Those 
issued  against  mortgages  of  tenants  must  have  a  fixed  date  of 
maturity,  while  those  issued  against  mortgages  of  landowners 
and  obligations  of  cooperative  societies  are  indeterminate  in 
duration  and  are  retired  by  purchase  or  by  drawing  lots  every 
half  year  to  an  amount  equal  to  that  paid  off  on  the  loans. 
Both  may  be  made  payable  to  bearer,  the  first  in  denomina- 
tions of  $20,  the  second  in  denominations  of  $40.  The  Minis- 
try of  Agriculture,  Commerce  and  Industry  supervises  all  the 
institutions  through  the  Agricultural  Council. 

Licenses  under  this  law  have  been  taken  out  by  many  sav- 
ings banks  and  cooperative  associations,  and  also  by  some  of 
the  agricultural  banks  (notably  in  Sardinia  and  the  BasUi- 
cata)  which  have  been  set  up  by  the  Government  with  the 
aid  of  public  funds  in  central,  southern,  and  insular  Italy. 


CHAPTER   XV 

SMAM.   HOLDINGS   IN   GEEAT   BEITAIN  AND   IRELAND 

Act  of  1908  Enables  Government  to  Take  Private  Land. — ^Land 
Leased  in  Small  Holdings. — County  Councils  in  Charge  of  Leas- 
ing.— ^Procedure. — ^Formation  of  Cooperative  Associations. — ^Land 
Court  of  Scotland. — Land  Holders  and  Small  Holders. — ^Work  of 
Scotch  Board  of  Agriculture. — Four  Of&cial  Bodies  in  Ireland. 
— ^Large  Loans  of  Board  of  Works. — Congested  Districts  Board 
in  West  of  Ireland. — Irish  Department  of  Agriculture  and  Tech- 
nical Instruction. — Credit  of  State  Extended  by  Estate  Commis- 
sioners for  Acquiring  Eeal  Estate. — ^Progress  of  Work. — ^History 
of  Land-purchase  Legislation. — Acts  Administered  by  Board  of 
Agriculture  and  Fisheries. 

The  Small  Holdings  and  Allotments  Act  of  1908  enables 
the  Government  of  Great  Britain,  through  the  proper  author- 
ities and  subject  to  certain  conditions,  to  take  all  the  land 
■which  any  individual  owns  in  England  and  Wales  in  excess 
of  50  acres  and  to  sell  or  lease  it  to  a  farmer  or  laborer. 
This  measure  is  so  drastic  that  many  believe  that  it  is 
the  preliminary  step  to  the  complete  nationalization  of  all 
lands  in  the  United  Kingdom.  Several  members  of  the 
peerage  have  already  made  arrangements  to  dispose  of 
vast  ancestral  estates  and  convert  them  into  cash,  in  order 
to  avoid  the  loss  vrhich  might  result  from  a  drop  in  real- 
estate  values  if  the  Government  should  become  more 
socialistic  and  go  extensively  into  the  business  of  acquir- 
ing land  for  sale  or  lease  to  the  have-nots  on  cheap  and 
easy  terms. 

Allotments  are  plots  not  exceeding  one  acre.  They  are 
acquired  for  leasing  to  agricultural  laborers.  Small  holdings 
are  par£els  of  agricultural  land  of  more  than  one  acre  and 
not  more  than  50  acres,  or,  if  exceeding  50  acres,  the  annual 

148 


GEEAT   BEITAIN"   AND   lEBLAKD  149 

return  of  ■which  as  estimated  for  the  income  tax  is  not  in 
excess  of  $350. 

The  county  councils  are  charged  with  the  duty  of  pro- 
viding such  small  holdings  for  persons  who  desire  to  buy  or 
lease  and  will  themselves  cultivate  the  holdings.  Two  com- 
missioners with  expert  and  practical  fcaowledge  of  agricul- 
ture have  been  appointed  by  the  Board  of  Agriculture  and 
Fisheries,  under  the  law,  to  ascertain  the  extent  to  which 
there  is  a  demand  for  small  holdings  or  would  be  if  suitable 
lands  were  available,  and  to  confer  with  the  county  councils 
to  devise  plans  to  satisfy  such  a  demand.  If  a  county  council 
ignores  the  recommendations  of  these  commissioners  or  the 
request  of  six  citizens,  the  Board  may  compel  it  to  act,  under 
penalty  of  paying  the  costs  resulting  from  its  neglect.  All 
plans  for  the  acquisition  of  lands,  whether  made  by  the  coun- 
cils or  by  the  conmiissioners,  must  be  passed  upon  by  the 
Board,  and  the  expense  thus  incurred  is  paid  out  of  a  fund 
provided  by  Parliament,  if  it  cannot  be  otherwise  recovered. 

Lands  acquired  for  small  holdings  by  a  county  may  be 
situated  within  or  without  its  borders.  A  county  may  join 
one  or  more  other  counties  in  arranging  a  plan.  If  it  can- 
not acquire  suitable  lands  by  agreement  with  the  owners,  the 
council  after  due  notice  may  order  the  desired  or  needed  land 
to  be  compulsorily  sold  or  leased.  The  order  becomes  effec- 
tive upon  confirmation  by  the  Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fish- 
eries. In  case  objections  are  raised  the  points  in  dispute  are 
settled  by  an  arbitrator  appointed  by  tfie  Board,  who  is 
allowed  to  hear  neither  lawyer  nor  expert  witness  unless 
otherwise  directed.  Parks,  public  grounds,  lands  used  for 
public  utility  or  for  the  convenience  or  comfort  of  a  dwell- 
ing house  or  farm  home,  or  which  are  under  50  acres  in 
extent,  cannot  be  taken  by  this  procedure  for  the  purpose 
of  creating  small  holdings.  If  the  order  specifies  that  the 
land  shall  be  acquired  compulsorily  on  lease  from  the  owner, 
the  period  must  be  not  less  than  14  or  more  than  35  years. 

After  a  county  has  bought  or  leased  the  land  it  desires 
or  needs,  either  by  agreement  or  by  compulsion,  it  may  adapt 
it  for  small  holdings  by  subdividing  and  fencing,  by  making 


150  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

roads,  drainage  or  irrigation  ditckes,  and  by  putting  up  such, 
buildings  as  may  be  necessary  to  make  it  suitable  for  occu- 
pancy. The  total  cost  of  the  acquisition  and  improvement 
of  the  tract  must  be  so  distributed  that  each  smaU  holding 
created  out  of  it  shall  bear  its  proportionate  share.  But  no 
county  may  incur  any  expense  or  obligation  in  carrying  out 
its  plans  which  would  raise  the  annual  tax  rate  more  than  a 
penny  in  the  pound. 

As  soon  as  the  tract  has  been  cut  up  into  small  holdings 
and  each  duly  registered,  the  county  must  proceed  to  dispose 
of  it.  The  conditions  of  tenure  are  that  the  occupier  of  each 
holding  shall  keep  it  in  a  good  state  of  cultivation,  and  will 
not  allow  intoxicating  liquors  to  be  sold  or  more  than  one 
dwelling  house  to  be  erected  thereon.  The  holdings  may 
be  sold  in  fee  if  the  county  bought  the  tract  by  agreement 
but  if  the  tract  was  acquired  on  lease  or  by  compulsory  sale, 
only  subleases  not  to  exceed  35  years  are  lawful.  The  sale 
or  sublease  may  be  to  individuals,  or  to  groups  of  individuals 
working  on  a  cooperative  basis,  or  to  associations  formed  for 
the  creation  and  development  of  small  holdings  and  so  orga- 
nized that  profits  are  prohibited  or  restricted.  The  purchase 
prices  or  rents  must  be  fixed  sufficiently  high  to  guard  the 
county  against  loss. 

For  each  small  holding  sold  outright  by  the  county,  the 
purchaser  must  pay  not  less  than  one-fifth  of  the  price  in 
cash;  one-fourth  may  be  secured  by  a  perpetual  rent-charge 
redeemable  in  the-  manner  provided  by  the  English  laws ;  and 
the  balance  may  be  secured  by  mortgage,  to  be  paid  off  half- 
yearly  in  instalments  of  principal  and  interest  or  by  a  ter- 
minable annuity.  The  longest  credit  which  a  county  may 
allow  on  such  a  sale  is  50  years.  The  borrower  may  dis- 
charge his  debt  in  advance,  or  he  may  be  accorded  a  renewal 
not  exceeding  five  years. 

Each  county  is  required  by  the  law  to  appoint  and  main- 
tain a  committee  consisting  in  whole  or  in  part  of  members 
of  the  council  to  attend  to  all  matters  relating  to  small  hold- 
ings. One  of  the  objects  of  the  committee  is  to  promote 
the  formation  of  cooperative  associations  among  the  occupiers 


GKEAT  BEITAIN  AND  lEELAND  151 

of  the  holdings,  for  banking,  insurance  and  all  agricultural 
purposes.  Counties  may  make  grants  or  advances  to  such 
associations  or  guarantee  advances  made  to  them.  The  coim- 
ty  may  also  assist  any  individual  tenant  to  buy  a  farm  of 
the  size  of  a  small  holding,  situated  within  its  borders,  by 
lending  on  mortgage  four-fifths  of  the  purchase  price  agreed 
upon  with  the  landlord. 

There  are  8,300  county  councils  and  local  authorities  in 
England  and  Wales  to  which  the  Small  Holdings  and  Allot- 
ments Act  applies,  but  up  to  1913  only  3,000  had  taken  ad- 
vantage of  it.  These  had  acquired  154,977  acres,  of  which 
about  two-thirds  was  purchased  and  the  rest  held  on  lease. 
Only  a  small  portion  had  been  resold.  The  great  majority  of 
the  small  holders  are  sublessees.  The  amount  which  has  been 
borrowed  by  the  counties  for  the  purchase  and  adaptation  of 
these  lands  exceeds  $13,250,000. 

In  Scotland,  since  1912,  the  relations  between  small  ten- 
ants and  owners  of  agricultural  lands  may  be  established  by 
judicial  proceedings  instead  of  by  private  contract,  if  either 
of  the  parties  so  desires.  For  this  purpose  a  law  of  1911 
created  a  special  Land  Court,  composed  of  five  members  ap- 
pointed by  the  Crown  upon  recommendation  of  the  Secretary 
for  Scotland,  and  a  Board  of  Agriculture,  composed  of  a 
chairman  and  two  commissioners  also  appointed  by  the  Crown 
upon  recommendation  of  the  Secretary  for  Scotland. 

A  smaU  tenant  is  one  with  a  holding  the  annual  rental 
of  which  does  not  exceed  $250  or,  if  exceeding  that  rental, 
is  not  over  50  acres  in  area.  Such  a  tenant  under  the  Scottish 
law  may  be  either  a  landholder  or  a  small  holder.  A  tenant 
is  designated  as  a  landholder  if  he  or  his  predecessors  in  the 
same  family  erected  the  buildings  and  made  the  other  im- 
provements or  the  larger  part  thereof  on  the  holding  with 
their  own  money  and  labor;  and  as  a  small  holder  if  the 
larger  portion  of  the  money  and  labor  therefor  were  furnished 
by  the  landlord. 

A  landholder  who  was  such  at  the  time  the  law  of  1911 
was  enacted  has  the  right  to  perpetual  occupancy  of  his 
holding.     Should  the  tenure  be  cancelled  for  any  reason,  he 


152  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

must  be  compensated  for  the  buildings  and  improvements, 
and  all  his  rights  descend  to  his  heirs  or  to  that  member  of 
his  family  to  whom  he  wills  them.  A  small  holder,  of  course, 
has  no  interest  in  the  buildings  and  improvements,  but  he 
has  the  right  to  continuous  renewals  of  his  lease  on  the 
terms  in  force  at  the  time  the  law  was  enacted,  and  the  right 
passes  to  his  heirs  or  may  be  willed  to  any  of  them.  If  the 
landlord  allows  the  improvements  or  buildings  to  get  out 
of  repair,  the  small  holder  may  be  declared  a  landholder. 

All  matters  in  dispute  between  landlords  and  landholders 
and  small  holders  are  determined  by  the  Land  Court,  whose 
decision  is  final  as  regards  the  facts.  Questions  of  law  may 
be  carried  to  the  Court  of  Sessions,  without  further  appeal 
to  the  House  of  Lords.  But  the  Land  Court  has  exclusive 
jurisdiction  over  the  rents;  it  may  raise  or  lower  them  to 
whatever  figure  it  deems  fair  and  the  landlord  must  abide 
by  its  decisions.  The  case  for  the  tenants  is  attended  to  by 
the  Scotch  Board  of  Agriculture,  which  selects  one  of  its 
members  as  a  special  commissioner  for  small  holdings  for  this 
purpose. 

The  Scotch  Board  of  Agriculture  is  charged  with  the 
general  duties  indicated  by  its  name.  In  addition  to  adjust- 
ing the  rights  of  tenants  on  lands  occupied  at  the  time  the 
law  of  1911  was  enacted,  the  Board  is  empowered  to  enlarge 
small  holdings  and  to  acquire  estates  for  subdivision  and  allot- 
ment to  small  holders.  If  the  land  desired  cannot  be  obtained 
by  contract  the  Board  may  acquire  it  compulsorily  by  pro- ' 
ceedings  before  the  Land  Court.  But  it  cannot  entirely  ex- 
propriate the  owner  or  divest  him  of  his  title,  as  is  permitted 
in  England  and  Ireland.  All  the  Scotch  Board  can  do  is  to 
compel  the  owner  to  turn  over  his  estate  to  be  prepared  and 
subdivided  for  small  holdings,  and  to  accept  as  tenants  those 
persons  to  whom  it  allots  the  holdings  at  the  rents  deter- 
mined by  the  Land  Court. 

The  Government  has  appropriated  about  $1,000,000  a 
year  to  be  used  by  the  Scotch  Board  of  Agriculture  for  carry- 
ing on  its  work.  This  fund  is  expended  in  preparing  and 
allotting  estates  for  small  holdings;  it  may  be  employed  also 


GEEAT  BEITAIN"   AND   lEELAND  153 

in  making  loans  to  public  authorities  for  that  purpose,  or  to 
small  holders  for  erecting  buildings  and  fences.  To  public 
authorities  the  Board  advances  no  more  than  three-fourths 
of  the  expense.  Loans  made  to  individuals  for  erecting  build- 
ings are  repayable  within  50  years  by  instalments  at  the  rate 
of  one  dollar  per  annum  for  every  $25  borrowed.  This  in- 
cludes interest,  payment  for  amortization  of  the  principal, 
and  the  premium  on  insurance.  Loans  granted  for  fencing 
are  repayable  within  seven  years.  A  mortgage  upon  the 
entire  right  of  the  tenant  in  the  holding  is  taken  as  security. 

The  procedure  for  enlarging  a  small  holding  is  similar  to 
that  for  acquiring  estates  for  subdivision,  except  that  no 
compulsory  step  may  be  taken  against  the  owner,  nor  can  the 
tenant  request  the  services  of  the  Board  until  he  has  first 
applied  to  his  landlord  and  been  refused.  Ko  small  holding 
obtained  through  intervention  of  the  state  in  Scotland  may 
be  mortgaged  or  sold  by  the  occupier. 

In  Ireland,  long-term  loans,  besides  free  grants,  are  made 
by  the  state  for  agricultural  purposes,  through  four  officiah 
bodies,  the  Board  of  Public  Works,  the  Congested  Districts! 
Board,  the  Department  of  Agriculture  and  Technical  In-| 
struction,  and  the  Estates  Commissioners.  The  loans  are  | 
usually  secured  by  a  charge  or  mortgage  on  real  estate,  but  | 
in  some  cases  personal  security  may  be  taken  or  no  security/ 
at  all  may  be  required.  -^ 

The  Board  of  Works  was  established  in  1831.  During  its 
long  career  it  has  advanced  large  amounts  to  farmers  for 
the  purposes  which  it  was  organized  to  promote,  namely, 
drainage,  subsoiling,  trenching  or  otherwise  deepening  or 
improving  the  soil,  irrigation  and  warping,  embanking  from 
rivers  and  tidal  waters,  building  and  repairing  fences,  mak- 
ing farm  roads,  clearing  away  rocks  and  stones,  reclaiming 
wastes,  planting  trees,  erecting  or  improving  farm  offices, 
farm  dwellings  and  laborers'  cottages,  and  the  erection  of 
mills  for  scutching  flax  and  the  construction  of  dams,  weirs 
and  watercourses  for  supplying  them  with  water. 

Borrowers  may  be  landowners  or  tenants:  if  tenants  of 
leaseholds,  the  annual  value  of  their  holdings  must  be  over 


\54  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

$58 ;  if  tenant-purchasers,  it  must  be  over  $34.  Tenants  from 
year  to  year,  that  is,  the  most  necessitous  class,  cannot  be  aided 
by  the  Board  of  Works.  Loans  to  landowners  must  be  for  sums 
not  less  than  $500,  except  for  erecting  farm  buildings,  when 
they  may  be  for  $250.  In  the  case  of  tenant-purchasers, 
loans  must  not  exceed  five  times  the  annual  value  of  the  hold- 
ings. In  the  case  of  tenant-occupiers,  no  loan  may  be  granted 
for  less  than  $175  or  for  more  than  $5,000.  In  ordinary 
circimistaiices  a  loan  will  not  be  granted  to  such  occupiers  for 
a  greater  sum  than  three  times  the  annual  value  of  the 
land.  A  mortgage  on  the  land  to  be  improved  is  always 
required  as  security  for  a  loan  from  the  Board.  The  money 
is  advanced  as  the  work  progresses  in  sums  equivalent  to  the 
amount  proved  by  the  borrower  to  have  been  expended  on 
the  land.  Eepayment  is  usually  by  an  annuity  of  6.5  per 
cent  rimning  for  22  years.  In  1913  about  $530,450  was  ad- 
vanced by  the  Board  of  Works,  of  which  97  per  cent  was  for 
the  erection  of  farm  buildings  and  cottages. 

The  Congested  Districts  Board  was  established  in  1891  for 
the  purpose  of  dealing  with  the  special  economic  problems  of 
the  poor  western  districts  of  Ireland.  The  Board  possesses 
wide  powers  and  discretion  for  taking  such  steps  as  it  deems 
proper  for  aiding  migrants,  or  emigrants  from  congested  dis- 
tricts, increasing  the  size  of  holdings,  and  developing  agri- 
culture by  improving  the  breed  of  live  stock  and  methods  of 
cultivation,  by  both  direct  and  indirect  means.  The  Board 
has  been  left  practically  imfettered  by  law  as  to  the  method 
of  expending  the  appropriations  intrusted  to  it,  which  now 
amoimt  to  $1,124,162  annually.  Of  this  amount  $100,000 
is  disposed  of  each  year  in  free  non-repayable  advances,  and 
the  rest  is  employed  largely  in  purchasing  and  improving  real 
estate  for  subdivision  and  resale.  The  credit  operations  of 
the  Board  are  insignificant,  amounting  to  only  $29,866 
in  1912. 

The  Irish  Department  of  Agriculture  and  Technical  In- 
struction upon  its  establishment  in  1899  took  over  some  of 
the  functions  of  the  Congested  Districts  Board,  and  will 
eventually  replace  it  in  all  agricultural  afEairs.    The  Depart- 


GEEAT   BEITAIN  AND   IKELAND  155 

ment  may  make  loans  to  individuals  for  any  agricnltural  pur- 
pose. The  total  amount  loaned  in  1913  was  $58,705.  Nearly 
one  half  went  for  the  purchase  of  bulls;  the  remainder  was 
loaned  for  fencing,  the  purchase  of  farm  implements  and 
stallions,  and  the  financing  of  agriciiltural  cooperative  credit 
societies.  The  Department  has  advanced  $535,000  to  date, 
but  very  little  of  it  was  in  the  form  of  loans  secured  by  real 
estate.  The  only  instances  in  which  real-estate  security  has 
been  taken  have  been  loans  for  the  erection  of  village  halls 
and  for  equipping  and  repairing  mills  for  scutching  flax. 

The  Estates  Commissioners,  who  number  three,  appointed 
for  life  by  the  Crown  and  charged  with  carrying  out  the 
provisions  of  the  Land  Purchase  Acts,  is  the  greatest  body 
not  only  in  Ireland  but  in  the  world  for  using  the  aid  and 
credit  of  the  state  for  the  purpose  of  enabling  farmers  to 
acquire  real  estate.  The  Estates  Commissioners  have  power 
to  sanction  the  expenditure  of  public  funds  not  only  on  works 
for  the  improvement  of  land  and  the  erection  of  buildings 
but  also  in  the  purchase  of  livestock,  seed  and  farm  imple- 
ments. These  expenditures,  however,  are  all  confined  to  the 
lands  purchased  by  the  Estates  Conamissioners  for  resale  to 
peasants.  The  prime  purpose  of  the  Estates  Commissioners 
is  to  bring  about  by  agreement  or  compulsion  the  transfer 
of  the  ownership  of  the  land  in  Ireland  from  the  large  pro- 
prietors to  the  peasants  who  occupy  and  cultivate  it.  Already 
they  have  effected  a  change  of  title  to  two-thirds  of  the  agri- 
cultural land,  committing  the  British  Government  to  obliga- 
tions amounting  to  hundreds  of  millions  of  dollars. 

Four-fifths  of  the  inhabitants  of  Ireland  are  farmers  or 
engaged  in  agricultural  pursuits.  Practically  all  farmers  are 
now  owners  of  the  farms  they  till  or  else  are  occupying  them 
at  fair  rents  judicially  fixed.  None  of  these  farms  is  over  30 
acres  in  area,  while  the  majority  are  under  15  acres  with 
many  ranging  between  one  and  five  acres.  The  long  struggle 
of  the  Irish  tenants  against  their  landlords  is  ended,  and 
the  bitter  hatred  engendered  by  generations  of  oppression  and 
reactive  violence  is  being  forgotten. 

The  land-purchase  legislation,  to  which  this  betterment 


156  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

of  rural  conditions  and  content  are  due,  comprises  a  series 
of  acts  covering  a  long  period  of  years.  In  1869  the  Irish 
Church  Act  enabled  occupiers  to  buy  glebe  lands,  the  state 
advancing  three-fourths  of  the  purchase  price  to  be  repaid 
by  an  annuity  of  four  per  cent  in  32  years.  The  act  of  1870, 
giving  the  tenant  the  right  to  dispose  of  his  interest  and  to 
receive  compensation  for  his  improvements,  contained  clauses 
which  authorized  the  Government  to  promote  land  purchase 
by  advancing  two-thirds  of  the  purchase  price  to  be  repaid  by 
an  annuity  of  five  per  cent  in  35  years.  These,  however,  were 
sporadic  attempts  inadequately  financed,  and  only  6,750  ten- 
ants acquired  title  to  their  holdings  thereby. 

A  clearly  defined  policy  of  a  national  character  in  respect 
to  the  land  was  not  adopted  for  Ireland  by  the  British  Govern- 
ment until  1881.  In  that  year  Gladstone  made  a  bold  effort 
to  adjust  matters  on  an  equitable  basis  by  the  Land  Law 
(Ireland)  Act,  giving  the  tenants  the  right  to  have  their  rents 
fixed  judicially  and  refixed  every  15  years  and  to  sell  their 
holdings  if  they  so  desired.  The  Government  undertook  also 
to  advance  three-fourths  of  the  purchase  price  or  one-half 
of  the  "fine"  to  acquire  a  "fee  farm"  tenure  to  tenants  who 
were  able  to  acquire  their  holdings  by  agreement  with  their 
landlords.  A  Land  Commission  was  appointed  to  carry  out 
this  measure.  In  1885  the  Land  Commission  was  empowered 
to  advance  the  entire  purchase  price  provided  a  deposit  was 
made  to  guarantee  the  payment  of  the  first  one-fifth,  and 
$25,000,000  was  appropriated  for  loans  to  tenants.  In  1891 
the  Government  began  to  issue  "guaranteed  land  stock"  for 
making  these  purchases.  This  stock  bore  2%  per  cent  interest 
per  annum,  but  the  Treasury  was  authorized  to  issue  2^  per 
cent  stock  as  soon  as  $50,000,000  of  the  first  kind  had  been 
issued.  An  annuity  of  four  per  cent  for  49  years  was  re- 
quired from  the  purchasing  tenant.  One-fourth  of  one  per 
cent  of  the  annuity  went  into  a  guarantee  fund  which  was 
allotted  among  the  various  counties.  Advances  for  purchas- 
ing holdings  in  any  county  were  limited  to  35  times  its  share 
in  the  guarantee  fund,  if  defaults  in  the  payment  of  annui- 
ties could  not  be  covered  by  this  fund,  the  deficiency  was 


GEEAT  BEITAIN   AND   IRELAND  157 

made  good  by  a  levy  on  the  eonaties.  In  1896  a  number  of 
amendments  to  the  law  were  made  respecting  the  fixing  of 
rents^  while  the  method  of  calculating  the  annuity  was 
changed.  The  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent  set  aside  for  cre- 
ating the  guarantee  fund  was  applied  to  the  reduction  of 
the  tenant's  debt,  and  an  extra  percentage  which  the  tenants 
had  been  required  to  pay  on  the  49-year  loans  for  the  first 
five  years  as  an  insurance  against  defaults  was  altogether 
abolished. 

By  virtue  of  the  operation  of  these  laws,  a  large  portion 
of  the  land  in  Ireland  by  1903  had  passed  over  to  the  ten- 
ants or  was  held  by  them  at  fixed  fair  rents.  The  landlords, 
realizing  that  their  absolute  tenure  was  doomed,  were  begin- 
ning to  prefer  to  sell  their  estates  to  remaining  mere  pen- 
sioners or  receivers  of  rent  at  rates  to  which  they  were  forced 
to  consent.  The  tenants,  on  the  other  hand,  were  discon- 
tented wherever  they  could  not  acquire  complete  control,  and 
in  that  year  the  Irish  Land  Act  was  enacted  to  put  the 
finishing  touches  on  the  Irish  land-purchase  legislation.  This 
act  reconstructed  the  Land  Commission  and  provided  for  the 
establishment  of  the  Estates  Commission,  placing  $500,000,- 
000  at  its  disposal  for  making  loans  to  tenants,  in  addition 
to  giving  $60,000,000  as  a  free  grant  to  enable  tenants  to  pay 
the  first  one-fourth  of  the  purchase  price  which  was  required 
to  be  paid  in  cash.  The  Estates  Commission  is  empowered  to 
acquire  lands  compulsorily  when  offers  made  by  it  are  re- 
fused, and  also  on  request  by  the  Congested  Districts  Board 
when  that  body  is  unable  to  acquire  by  agreement  the  land 
desired.  In  1909  the  annuity  of  the  purchasing  tenants  was 
fixed  at  3%  per  cent  per  annum,  and  the  period  for  the 
extinction  of  the  loans  was  extended  from  49  to  68%  years. 

The  number  of  agricultural  holdings  in  Ireland  was  found 
by  the  census  of  1911  to  be  535,675.  Up  to  March,  1913, 
applications  to  have  "fair  rents"  fixed  had  been  allowed  for 
455,000  of  these  holdings.  As  regards  sales,  if  one  person 
be  reckoned  for  every  loan,  over  240,000  occupiers  have  been 
made  owners  in  fee,  under  the  laws,  of  over  8,000,000  acres 
of  good  agricultural  lands.    Including  the  bonds  which  have 


158  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

been  issued,  the  sums  guaranteed,  advanced  or  promised  by 
the  state  amount  to  $622,404,180.  This  stupendous  ajnount 
will  have  to  be  increased  to  over  one  billion  dollars  if  the 
plans  which  have  been  devised  to  make  all  Irish  tenants  the 
actual  owners  of  the  lands  they  occupy  are  carried  to  com- 
pletion. The  state's  credit  has  been  pledged  on  all  land 
stock  or  bonds  which  have  been  issued,  but  as  only  a  few 
defaults  have  been  made  by  borrowers,  it  has  not  suffered 
much  loss. 

Besides  the  laws  enumerated,  the  aid  and  credit  of  the 
state  for  land  improvement  in  Great  Britain  and  Ireland 
have  been  pledged  by  a  number  of  acts  which  date  back  many 
years,  the  administration  of  which  is  now  entrusted  to  the 
Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries.  The  earliest  of  these 
land-improvement  acts  were  those  passed  between  the  years 
1846  and  1856  for  appropriating  and  lending  public  moneys 
to  facilitate  works  of  drainage  on  the  security  of  the  lands 
benefited  thereby.  The  Act  of  1846  empowered  the  Treasury, 
on  application  of  the  Inclosure  Commissioners  (now  the 
Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries),  to  advance  for  such 
works  sums  not  exceeding  $10,000,000  in  Great  Britain  and 
$5,000,000  in  Ireland.  Further  advances  to  the  amount  of 
$10,000,000  for  Great  Britain  and  $1,000,000  for  Ireland 
were  made  by  the  act  of  1850.  The  landowner  who  applied 
for  a  loan  under  these  acts  had  to  file  with  his  application  a 
description  of  the  land,  the  muniments  of  title,  a  plan  of  the 
proposed  works,  and  an  estimate  of  their  cost.  If  approved 
by  the  Commissioners,  a  provisional  certificate  was  issued  to 
the  landowner  declaring  that  when  the  works  had  been  prop- 
erly executed,  the  necessary  sum  would  be  advanced  for  the 
cost  of  the  works  and  incidental  expenses.  Then,  if  no  one 
having  any  estate  in  or  charge  on  the  land  presented  a  valid 
dissent,  when  the  commissioners  were  satisfied  that  the  works 
were  duly  carried  out,  they  issued  a  final  certificate  and  an 
order  for  granting  the  loan.  After  the  money  had  been 
turned  over,  the  land  became  charged  with  the  payment  to  the 
Crown  of  a  rent  charge  at  a  rate  sufficient  to  extinguish  the 
debt  at  the  end  of  22  years.     These  acts  required  that  the 


GEEAT  BEITAIISr  AND  IRELAND  159 

works  should  be  capable  of  being  finished  within  five  years, 
and  limited  the  advances  to  any  one  landowner  to  $25,000. 
The  landowner  could  assign  his  certificate  to  any  person 
agreeing  to  advance  the  money,  and  the  latter  was  entitled  to 
receive  the  advance  from  the  Treasury.  Money  borrowed 
from  other  persons  or  by  the  landowner  himself  could  be 
made  a  charge  on  the  lands  improved,  while  the  works  and 
the  Hen  for  them  could  be  extended  over  adjacent  lands  for 
making  outfalls  and  opening  drains  and  watercourses.  All 
appropriations  under  these  acts  have  been  exhausted. 

These  acts  provided  also  for  the  incorporation  of  the 
General  Land  Drainage  and  Improvement  Company  for 
England  and  Wales;  the  Lands  Improvement  Company  for 
England,  Wales  and  Scotland;  the  Scottish  Draiaage  and 
Improvement  Company,  for  Scotland  alone;  and  the  Land 
Loan  and  Enfranchisement  Company  for  England,  Wales, 
Scotland  and  Ireland.  The  organization,  objects  and  powers 
of  these  companies  for  their  respective  territories  are  sub- 
stantially the  same.  They  were  empowered  to  make  loans  for 
drainage,  irrigation,  embanking,  enclosing  and  reclaiming, 
the  making  of  farm  roads,  and  the  construction  of  farm 
buildings,  mills,  and  hydraulic  works  for  farm  purposes  and 
cultivation.  They  were  given  as  security  for  their  loans  a 
charge  imposed  by  law  on  the  lands  so  improved,  which  for 
the  company  first  mentioned  might  run  for  31  years  for  build- 
ings and  50  years  for  other  improvements ;  for  the  other  com- 
panies the  period  might  not  exceed  40  years. 

In  1864  these  acts  were  consolidated  and  so  amended 
as  to  enable  landowners  of  limited  interests  to  charge  their 
lands  with  money  subscribed  for  the  construction  of  rail- 
ways and  canals.  Such  a  landowner  desirous  of  borrowing 
or  advancing  money,  according  to  the  amended  act,  must 
file  his  application  in  the  usual  way,  showing  that  the  use  of 
the  money  so  subscribed  will  permanently  increase  the  value 
of  his  lands.  If  approved  by  the  Board  a  provisional  order 
is  issued  which  names  the  landowner,  the  maximum  sum  to 
be  charged,  the  rate  of  interest,  not  to  exceed  five  per  cent, 
and  the  term  for  repayment,  which  may  not  exceed  40  years. 


160  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  order  becomes  final  upon  completion  of  the  works,  and 
the  landowner  may  assign  the  charge  created  thereby  either 
absolutely  or  by  way  of  security  to  one  of  the  improvement 
companies  or  to  any  one  who  may  agree  to  advance  the  money 
subscribed  towards  the  building  of  the  railway  or  canal  or  for 
any  of  the  other  authorized  improvements.  The  order  cre- 
ating the  charge  is  never  granted  unless  it  be  shown  that 
the  improvements  will  effect  a  permanent  increase  in  the 
yearly  value  of  the  land  exceeding  the  annuity  or  amount 
proposed  to  be  charged  on  it.  This  requirement  as  to  in- 
creased yearly  value  does  not  apply,  however,  in  the  case  of 
loans  for  prom.otiag  cultivation.  The  Board  may  extend  the 
period  of  repayment  of  improvement  charges  in  certain  cases 
not  sooner  than  seven  and  not  later  than  ten  years  from  the 
date  of  the  order  creating  the  charge. 

The  improvements  mentioned  by  the  early  laws  were  all 
of  an  agricultural  character,  but  the  list  has  been  extended 
by  recent  acts  so  as  to  include  the  building  of  laborers'  cot- 
tages, mansion  houses,  and  various  other  objects  not  agri- 
cultural. The  total  of  the  amounts  raised  on  the  security 
of  charges  created  by  these  acts  amounted  in  1910  to  $91,- 
938,594. 


CHAPTEE   XVI 

AUSTEIA-HUNGAET,  EUSSIA,  AND   THE  BALKAN  STATES 

Provincial  Mortgage  Institutions  of  Austria. — Their  Loans. — ^History 
of  These  Lastitutions. — ^Land  Credit  in  Hungary. — Hungarian 
Eoden-Kredit  Institut. — Administration. — National  Land  Credit 
Institute  for  Small  Holders. — ^National  Federation  of  Hungarian 
Land  Credit  Institutions. — Land  Credit  Institute  at  Nagy- 
Szeben. — ^Large  Eussian  Projects. — Colonization  of  Siberia. — 
— Peasant's  State  Land  Bank. — Distribution  of  Land  to  Eman- 
cipated Serfs. — Operations  of  the  Bank. — ^Work  of  the  Land  Com- 
missioners.— Aid  for  Home  Colonization  in  Finland. — ^Eural 
Banks  of  Communes. — Mortgage  Society  of  Finland. — Territorial 
Credit  in  Livonia,  Esthonia,  and  Courland. — Government  Con- 
fiscation of  Nobility's  Estates  in  Eoumania. — ^Landschaft  Sys- 
tem and  Eural  Bank. — Bond  and  Mortgage  Institution  of  Servia. 

Theee  are  provincial  mortgage  institutions  in  all  but 
two  of  the  crown  provinces  of  Austria.  These  concerns  have 
neither  capital  stock,  shareholders,  nor  members.  They  are 
simply  bureaus  or  departments  in  the  provincial  administra- 
tions, managed  by  the  public  authorities.  They  extend  credit 
on  both  rural  and  urban  properties,  and  to  the  state,  prov- 
inces, municipalities,  and  public  corporations  empowered  to 
extend  such  credit.  But  their  chief  object  is  the  lifting  of 
burdensome  encumbrances  on  farm  lands  and  converting 
them  into  easy  long-time  contracts  at  a  low  interest  rate. 
No  profit  is  aimed  at. 

The  loans  are  made  not  in  cash  but  in  debentures,  but 
the  borrowers  are  not  jointly  and  severally  liable  as  in  the 
old  German  landschafts.  The  security  for  these  debentures 
comprises,  first,  the  mortgaged  properties,  then  certain  re- 
serves and  funds,  and  finally  the  guaranty  of  the  issuing 
provinces.    There  is,  of  course,  no  mortgage  security  for  the 

161 


163  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

commimal  debentures.  The  debentures  are  made  payable  to 
bearer,  to  be  redeemed  ■within  certain  long  periods,  and  may 
be  recalled  by  the  province  at  any  time.  No  limit  is  set  for 
the  amount  which  may  be  issued,  except  that  it  must  not 
exceed  the  amount  of  the  outstanding  loans.  Debentures  ard 
withdrawn  by  lot  or  purchase  as  the  loans  are  paid  off.  Bor- 
rowers may  use  them  at  their  face  value  in  making  payments, 
and  they  are  lawful  investments  for  the  funds  of  municipali- 
ties, districts,  corporations,  churches,  charitable  and  public 
establishments,  and  trustees.  They  may  be  deposited  also 
to  secure  the  fidelity  bonds  given  by  public  officials  and  em- 
ployees. 

Only  amortizable  long-time  loans  are  granted.  Most  of 
them  run  from  30  to  60  years;  the  average  is  54%  years, 
extinguished  by  an  annuity  of  4^^  per  cent.  The  rate  of  in- 
terest is  now  four  per  cent  in  most  provinces.  The  interest 
for  the  past  20  years  has  not  been  five  per  cent  over  that 
figure.  Besides  the  interest  rate  on  the  debentures  exchanged 
for  his  mortgage  and  the  annual  instalments  on  the  principal 
of  the  loan,  the  borrower  must  pay  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent 
toward  working  expenses  and  the  reserve.  In  institutions  in 
which  the  reserve  has  reached  five  to  ten  per  cent  of  the  de- 
bentures in  circulation,  this  latter  charge  is  reduced,  or  omit- 
ted during  the  first  ten  years  of  the  loan.  In  many  provinces 
it  is  done  away  with  altogether  for  poor  persons.  Borrowers 
may  make  repayment  in  cash  at  any  time,  but  six  months' 
notice  must  be  given  for  repayments  by  debentures.  After 
loans  or  any  parts  of  them  have  been  repaid,  the  corre- 
sponding debentures,  which  have  been  purchased  or  retired 
by  lot,  are  destroyed. 

The  first  of  these  Austrian  provincial  mortgage  institu- 
tions was  founded  in  1865,  and  the  last  in  1869.  The  Galician 
Boden-Kredit  Verein  may  be  mentioned  in  connection  with 
them.  This  institution  was  founded  in  1841  for  large  estates 
in  Galicia  and  Bukowina  as  a  landschaft  of  the  old  German 
style,  and  members  are  jointly  and  severally  liable  on  its 
debentures.  These  institutions  hold  21  per  cent  of  the  mort- 
gage loans  granted  by  public  concerns  in  Austria. 


AUSTKIA,  KUSSIA,  AND  BALKAN  STATES   163 

The  organization  of  land  credit  in  Hungary  began  in 
1767,  when  Maria  Theresa  had  a  survey  made  of  manorial 
estates  and  placed  the  serfs  under  the  protection  of  the  Ur- 
barial  Court,  upon  which  she  conferred  the  exclusive  power 
of  dispossessing  the  serfs  and  of  fixing  the  size  of  the  hold- 
ings which  they  might  possess.  The  serfs  were  known  as 
"urbarians."  Alongside  of  them  arose  another  class  of  ten- 
ants called  "curialists"  or  "contractuaJists,"  because  of  the 
fact  that  their  right  of  possession  rested  upon  contracts  with 
their  noble  landlords.  The  curialists  paid  head  tax  but  not 
the  land  tax;  the  urbarians  paid  both.  In  1848  compulsory 
labor,  tithes  and  dues  were  altogether  abolished  and  the  ur- 
barians were  made  freeholders.  The  curialists  then  thought 
that  they  should  hold  possession  of  their  holdings  without 
fulfilling  their  contracts,  and  indeed  many  were  allowed  to 
do  BO,  the  nobles  having  been  intimidated  by  the  agrarian 
troubles  in  1846  when  the  serfs  in  Galicia  rose  and  massa- 
cred their  landlords.  Fiually,  however,  the  Government 
adopted  the  practice  of  taking  over  large  estates  wherever 
agrarian  troubles  were  acute,  and  parceling  them  out  to  the 
peasants,  giving  the  landlords  bonds  by  way  of  compensa- 
tion. 

This  change  completely  revolutionized  agricultural  con- 
ditions. The  peasants  who  formerly  were  content  with  six 
to  ten  cents  a  day  demanded  five  times  that  amount  or  else 
refused  to  work.  Labor  became  scarce.  The  Turkish  wars 
increased  the  general  impoverishment,  and  landowners,  espe- 
cially the  extravagant  nobles,  were  unable  to  pay  their  taxes 
or  even  to  obtain  a  living  from  their  farms.  In  1857  the 
National  Bank  of  Austria  tried  to  render  assistance,  but  did 
very  little  good  because  land  registers  were  kept  inaccu- 
rately and  mortgages  were  unsafe.  Consequently,  most  of  the 
landlords  were  forced  to  the  necessity  of  selling  the  bonds 
which  they  had  received  from  the  state  at  a  very  heavy  dis- 
count, while  many  of  them  could  not  obtain  credit  at  all  even 
at  the  ruinous  rates  then  prevalent.  In  1858  George  Mailath 
addressed  a  circular  to  the  principal  landowners  of  the  coun- 
try, calling  attention  to  their  needs  and  mgiag  them  to  estab- 


164  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

lish  a  land  bank  on  plans  which  he  had  formulated  partly 
on  the  German  landschaft  model.  A  sufficient  number  hav- 
ing responded  to  his  call,  a  bank  called  the  Hungarian  Boden- 
Kredit  Institut  of  Budapest  was  organized  on  July  1,  1863. 

The  Hungarian  Boden-Kredit  Institut,  or  Land-Credit 
Institution,  was  not  organized  for  gain.  It  was  founded  by 
209  noble  landowners  inspired  by  patriotic  motives.  Its  capi- 
tal of  $821,730  was  created  by  a  contribution  of  $245,000 
from  the  state  and  $576,730  subscribed  by  the  founders.  The 
smallest  share  was  $2,450,  and  each  founder  paid  for  his 
share  by  giving  one-tenth  of  its  face  value  in  cash  and  nine 
equal  'notes  for  the  balance.  The  last  of  these  notes  were 
redeemed  in  1876  and  returned  to  the  founders,  but  the  cash 
is  still  retained  and  draws  five  per  cent  interest  a  year. 

The  chief  authority  in  the  Institut  is  the  founders'  assem- 
bly, composed  of  the  founders  and  their  successors,  in  which 
no  person  has  more  than  one  vote  or  may  hold  more  than  nine 
proxies.  Twenty  founders  representing  at  least  30  votes  con- 
stitute a  quorum.  Under  this  body  is  the  general  assembly 
of  the  borrowers.  Those  who  have  received  loans  of  $24,500 
or  over  have  one  vote  each,  but  no  more.  Those  who  have 
received  loans  under  that  amount  must  group  themselves  by 
districts  and  may  send  to  the  general  assembly  one  delegate 
for  every  $196,000  of  loans.    All  borrowers  become  members. 

The  administration  of  the  Institut  comprises  a  board  of 
directors,  a  committee  of  supervision,  and  the  usual  staff  of 
officers.  The  board  of  directors  consists  of  a  president  elected 
for  three  years  at  an  annual  meeting  of  the  general  assembly 
and  chosen  from  among  three  persons  proposed  by  the  foun- 
ders' assembly,  and  at  least  three  and  at  most  five  other 
members  chosen  by  the  committee  of  supervision.  Persons 
not  members  of  the  Institut  may  be  elected  to  serve  on  the 
board.  The  committee  of  supervision  consists  of  36  mem- 
bers, one  half  of  whom  are  chosen  by  the  general  assembly 
and  one  half  by  the  founders'  assembly.  A  portion  of  them 
are  renewed  at  regular  intervals. 

The  board  is  the  executive  head  of  the  Institut,  but  at 
least  three  of  the  supervisors  must  attend  the  board's  meet- 


AUSTEIA,  EUSSIA,  AND  BALKAN"  STATES   165 

ings  when  loans  are  being  considered,  and  no  loan  may  be 
granted  unless  a  majority  of  the  attending  supervisors  con- 
sent thereto.  The  committee  of  supervision  watches  over 
all  other  affairs,  prepares  the  annual  report,  and  has  such 
other  high  functions  that  it  is  practically  the  ruling  power. 
Local  committees  of  borrowing  members  act  as  agents  and 
guard  the  interests  of  the  Institut  in  the  provinces.  The 
by-laws  may  be  amended  or  the  Institut  itself  dissolved  by 
the  general  assembly,  but  only  upon  a  proposal  submitted  by 
the  founders'  assembly,  which  is  convened  by  the  board  of 
directors.  No  resolution  of  this  nature,  however,  has  any 
effect  until  approved  by  the  Hungarian  Government.  A  spe- 
cial commissioner  appointed  by  the  Government  is  charged 
with  the  duty  of  seeiag  that  the  Institut  observes  the  laws 
and  conducts  its  business  in  a  satisfactory  way.  He  must 
countersign  the  annual  report,  may  attend  all  meetings  of 
members  and  officers,  and  is  empowered  to  set  on  foot  what- 
ever investigations  he  deems  advisable. 

The  objects  of  the  Institut  are  to  grant  loans  to  indi- 
viduals and  cooperative  associations  on  the  security  of  rural 
properties,  to  finance  land  improvement  and  reclamation 
projects,  to  receive  deposits,  to  do  commercial  banking,  and 
to  purchase  mortgage  loans  made  to  small  holders  by  the 
cooperative  credit  societies  affiliated  with  the  Hungarian 
Central  Society  for  Cooperative  Credit  described  in  a  later 
chapter.  The  Institut  operates  entirely  in  the  interest  of 
borrowers,  an^  for  this  reason  the  Government  has  granted 
it  special  privileges  by  exempting  it  from  taxes  on  business 
done  and  from  stamp  duties  and  by  recognizing  its  debentures 
as  legal  investments  for  trustee  funds.  The  debentures  is- 
sued on  land-improvement  projects  are  non-taxable.  Sum- 
mary proceedings  may  be  resorted  to  against  debtors  in 
default. 

Except  in  the  ease  of  the  mortgages  of  small  homestead- 
ers, the  minimum  for  loans  is  $4,900.  The  majority  of  loans 
actually  granted  are  for  sums  of  less  than  $24,500.  Long- 
term  loans  are  subject  to  obligatory  amortization  and  are 
made  in  debentures  according  to  the  German  landschaft  plan. 


166  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

Consequently,  the  rate  of  interest  on  the  loan  as  well  as  its 
length  depends  upon  that  of  the  debentures.  The  borrower 
has  the  right  to  choose  debentures  of  the  rate  and  term  he 
wishes  among  those  issued.  In  1895  the  Institut  issued  3.5 
per  cent  debentures  redeemable  in  63  years  by  an  annuity  of 
4  per  cent  from  the  borrower,  but  these  were  never  quoted  at 
par,  and  the  lowest  now  issued  are  four  per  cents.  In  addition 
to  the  interest  and  yearly  instalment  on  his  loan  the  bor- 
rower must  pay  0.06  per  cent  into  the  reserve  and  one  per 
cent  into  the  guaranty  fimd.  The  latter  is  returned  in  full 
after  the  debt  is  finally  paid,  if  no  losses  have  occurred.  At 
present  the  borrower  pays  no  commission  for  the  sale  of  his 
debentures  nor  any  contribution  toward  working  expenses, 
although  the  Institut  is  authorized  to  make  these  charges. 
In  1912  the  amounts  due  to  the  Institut,  including  loans 
made  for  land-improvement  and  reclamation  projects,  ex- 
ceeded $119,000,000,  against  which  about  $100,000,000  of 
debentures  were  in  circulation.  Members,  that  is,  borrowers, 
and  the  founders  are  collectively  liable  on  these  bonds.  In 
1883  the  state  borrowed  $1,713,000  and  so  became  a  member 
of  the  Institut.  One  per  cent  of  the  net  profits  must  be  de- 
voted to  some  agricultural  object  of  a  public  nature.  The  rest 
is  used  for  increasing  the  capital.  This  with  the  reserves 
gives  the  Institut  (1910)  a  working  fund  of  its  own  exceeding 
$10,000,000. 

In  1879  the  National  Land  Credit  Institute  for  Small 
Landowners  of  Hungary  was  founded  at  Budapest  on  prac- 
tically the  same  lines  as  the  Boden-Kredit  Institut  and  en- 
dowed by  the  state  with  $245,000  free  of  interest.  There 
are,  however,  some  material  points  of  difference.  Founders' 
shares  in  the  new  Institute  are  $49,  $245  and  $2,450,  and 
draw  five  per  cent  dividends.  These  shares  will  begin  to  be 
paid  back  when  the  reserves  reach  $1,470,000.  Each  founder 
is  entitled  to  as  many  votes  as  he  has  $49  shares.  Ordinary 
members,  that  is,  borrowers,  have  one  vote  for  each  group 
representing  $122,500  of  loans.  There  is  no  special  founders' 
assembly,  the  chief  power  in  this  institution  being  lodged 
in  the  general  assembly  of  the  members  to  which  the  founders 


AUSTEIA,  EUSSIA,  AKD  BALKAN  STATES   167 

also  belong.  The  management  is  entrusted  to  a  president 
and  vice-president,  assisted  by  three  advisors,  who  constitute 
the  board  of  management,  and  to  a  committee  of  nine  vfhose 
duty  it  is  to  examine  the  accounts.  Both  bodies  are  elected 
by  the  general  assembly. 

This  institution  for  small  holders  has  the  same  privileges 
and  powers  which  were  conferred  upon  the  older  Institut, 
with  the  exception  that  its  business  is  confined  entirely  to 
granting  real-estate  credit  in  small  amounts.  The  smallest 
loan  is  $73.50,  and  none  can  exceed  50  per  cent  of  the  value 
of  the  mortgaged  land.  They  are  made  either  in  cash  or 
debentures.  The  interest  rate  is  now  usually  four  per  cent, 
in  addition  to  which  the  borrower  pays  one-fourth  of  one 
per  cent  toward  cost  of  business,  and  one  per  cent  for  amorti- 
zation, or  a  total  of  5.25  per  cent  to  extinguish  the  loan  in 
50  years.  The  Institute  lends  on  mortgages  assigned  to  it 
by  the  Hungarian  Central  Society  for  Cooperative  Credit 
and  is  very  active  in  aiding  home  colonization  and  iu  dis- 
mortgaging the  land.  At  the  end  of  1912  its  outstanding 
loans  amounted  to  approximately  $54,390,000,  founders' 
shares  $2,082,500,  and  reserves  $3,756,585.  These  loans  and 
funds,  together  with  the  joint  and  several  liability  of  the 
founders  and  members,  that  is,  borrowers,  are  the  security 
for  the  debentures. 

The  latest  step  taken  by  the  Hungarian  Government  to 
help  the  poorer  agricultural  classes  was  the  creation  in  1911 
of  the  National  Federation  of  Hungarian  Land  Credit  Insti- 
tutions. The  principal  objects  of  the  Federation  are  to  take 
over  the  management  of  large  estates  and  allot  and  sublease 
them  to  small  holders;  to  assist  such  persons  to  acquire  or 
improve  small  holdings,  particularly  those  who  are  members 
of  the  cooperative  societies  afiBliated  with  the  Hungarian  Cen- 
tral Society  for  Cooperative  Credit;  to  effect  the  conversion 
of  existing  burdensome  encumbrances  into  mortgages  on  easy 
terms;  to  acquire  pastures  for  the  common  use  of  farmers; 
to  construct  dwellings  for  agricultural  laborers ;  and  generally 
to  carry  out  the  policy  of  the  Government  in  respect  to  land. 
The  Government  endowed  it  with  $1,960,000,  required  the 


168  EUEAL    CEEDITS. 

Boden-Kredit  Institut,  the  National  Land  Credit  Institute 
for  Small  Holders,  and  the  Hungarian  Central  Society  for 
Cooperative  Credit  to  subscribe  $1,715,000  toward  its  capital, 
and  turned  over  $2,450,000  of  valuable  securities  as  a  guar- 
anty fund  for  its  debentures.  Its  membership  is  open  only 
to  the  state,  these  three  institutions,  and  such  individuals  as 
may  subscribe  to  founders'  shares  of  $34,500  with  dividends 
limited  to  four  per  cent.    No  individuals  have  yet  subscribed. 

The  Federation  enjoys  the  same  privileges  as  those  pos- 
sessed by  the  Hungarian  Central  Society  for  Cooperative 
Credit,  but  it  is  much  more  intimately  connected  with  the 
Government.  The  president  and  two  members  of  the  board 
of  directoi-s  are  appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Finance,  the 
vice-president  and  another  member  of  the  board  by  the  Min- 
ister of  Agriculture.  The  members  so  appointed  are  selected 
from  the  respective  departments  of  these  ministers,  and  they 
may  stop  any  act  of  the  management  until  passed  on  by  the 
Government.  All  plans  relating  to  the  purchase  and  leasing 
of  estates  or  the  sale  of  land  are  subject  to  the  approval  of 
the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  while  questions  regarding  the 
issuing  of  debentures  and  the  methods  of  granting  credit  are 
determined  by  the  Minister  of  Finance. 

Another  mortgage-bond  concern  based  on  the  joint  and 
several  liability  of  borrowers  in  Hungary  is  the  Land  Credit 
Institute  at  Nagy-Szeben.  Its  peculiarity  lies  in  the  fact 
that  the  holders  of  the  debentures  are  allowed  to  be  repre- 
sented at  the  meetings  of  the  members  and  have  one  vote  for 
every  $4,900  of  debentures  in  circulation. 

When  we  turn  to  Russia,  the  magnitude  of  the  homestead 
and  small-holdings  projects  of  Eussia  makes  those  of  all 
other  nations  except  Great  Britain  sink  into  insignificance. 
Hundreds  upon  hundreds  of  thousands  of  Eussian  farmers 
have  acquired  millions  of  acres  worth  billions  of  dollars  by 
means  of  money  and  credit  facilities  siipplied  by  the  Govern- 
ment. The  Government's  projects,  which  began  with  the  lib- 
eration of  the  serfs,  comprises  the  colonization  of  the  public 
domains  in  Siberia,  the  redistribution  of  the  myriads  of  plots 
of  the  peasantry  of  European  Eussia,  and  the  increase  of  the 


AUSTEIA,  EUSSIA,  AFD  BALKAN  STATES    169 

area  of  agricultural  lands  held  in  fee  simple  by  those  who 
cultivate  them. 

The  colonization  of  Siberia  is  conducted  by  the  Internal 
Emigration  Service.  This  has  an  annual  appropriation  of 
$13,875,000,  out  of  ■which  homesteaders  are  granted  loans  and 
free  transportation  when  necessary.  More  than  3,000,000 
persons  have  gone  into  Siberia,  one  half  of  them  in  the  three 
years  between  1907  and  1910,  and  the  number  is  now  so 
large  that  the  Service  with  its  3,000  officials  is  unable  to  cope 
with  the  situation.  At  least  700,000  of  the  emigrants  are 
working  as  day  laborers  while  awaiting  their  allotments 
(1910). 

The  two  other  projects  are  conducted  by  the  Peasants' 
State  Land  Bank  acting  in  conjunction  or  in  harmony  with 
district,  regional  and  provincial  land  commissioners.  These 
are  public  bodies  composed  of  members  in  the  main  selected 
from  official  life.  The  lower  commission  is  subordinated  to 
the  higher,  and  all  are  subject  to  the  control  of  the  Agricul- 
tural Land  Commission  at  St.  Petersburg,  which  serves  as 
a  court  of  last  instance  in  matters  withia  their  jurisdiction. 
The  Bank,  which  is  the  largest  land-credit  institution  ia  the 
world,  is  the  financial  organ  of  the  Government  in  its  land 
policies.    It  was  originally  founded  to  help  ex-serfs  only. 

The  emancipation  of  the  Eussian  serfs  on  the  crown  lands 
occurred  on  June  20,  1858,  on  the  feudal  estates  February 
19,  1861,  and  on  the  public  domains  January  18,  1861.  All 
the  serfs  were  given  the  right  to  acquire  enough  land  to  live 
on.  The  regulations  concerning  these  allotments  were  pro- 
mulgated for  the  first  two  classes  in  1863  and  1866,  but 
for  the  last  class  not  until  1891.  The  regulations  are  not  aU 
alike  but  generally  each  ex-serf  was  granted  a  piece  of  land 
equal  in  size  or  area  to  that  which  he  occupied  at  the  time 
of  his  emancipation.  In  this  way  22,396,069  ex-serfs  came 
into  the  possession  of  315,508,108  acres,  an  acreage  greater 
than  that  of  the  cultivated  lands  in  Germany,  France  and 
England  combined.  The  total  value  of  these  lands  exceeded 
$1,030,000,000.  It  was  turned  over,  however,  not  to  the  ex- 
serfs  directly  but  to  the  mirs,  or  counties,  in  which  they  were 


170  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

located,  and  these  counties  were  entrusted  with  its  distribu- 
tion and  were  made  responsible  for  the  payment  of  the  an- 
nuities. 

It  took  years,  of  course,  to  make  this  distribution,  and  in 
the  meantime  the  undistributed  land  was  held  in  common, 
with  title  in  the  county,  and  aU  peasants  therein  were  collec- 
tively liable  for  the  annuities  due  the  Crown  and  state.  The 
peasants  were  forbidden  to  seU  or  otherwise  dispose  of  their 
allotments.  The  parceling  of  the  lands  was  badly  done. 
Each  peasant  wanted  a  little  woodland,  a  water  right,  a  gar- 
den patch,  a  farm  and  a  place  in  which  to  live  in  his  village. 
Many  a  peasant  had  50  to  100  plots,  and  the  average  was  20 
plots  for  each,  of  which  the  area  was  between  24.71  and 
165.57  acres  in  most  counties.  This  led  to  poor  farming 
and  most  of  the  peasants  were  unable  to  pay  their  annui- 
ties. Those  who  had  acquired  ownership,  either  from  the 
counties  or  noble  landlords,  were  becoming  mere  tenants  at 
rack  rent,  and  their  plight  was  worse  than  under  their  former 
bondage.  These  conditions  acted  adversely  on  agriculture  to 
the  damage  of  the  nation,  so  the  Government  resolved  to  in- 
tervene in  order  to  assist  the  ex-serfs  in  redeeming  their 
land  from  its  burden  of  accumulated  and  running  charges, 
and  also  to  help  those  who  had  lost  their  holdings  to  recover 
them.    The  Peasants'  State  Land  Bank  was  the  result. 

The  Bank  was  established  in  1882  and  opened  its  doors 
in  1883  with  an  annual  subsidy  of  $2,575,000.  It  is  owned 
and  operated  by  the  state,  and  its  objects,  which  have  been 
extended  from  time  to  time,  are  now  to  make  loans  to  indi- 
vidual farmers,  to  associations  of  three  or  more  farmers,  and 
to  counties,  and  to  purchase  agricultural  lands  to  be  subdi- 
vided, allotted,  and  sold  on  mortgage  to  farmers.  Purchases 
of  this  kind  are  not  made  in  cash.  The  bank  gives  the  owner 
of  a  desirable  tract  which  he  is  willing  to  sell  certificates,  or 
rather  shares,  drawing  four  per  cent  interest,  which  may  be 
converted  into  a  book  of  notes  and  coupon  bearing  six  per 
cent  interest,  the  principal  to  be  repaid  in  ten  equal  instal- 
ments after  the  sixth  year. 

At  the  beginning  of  1911  the  Bank  had  14,537,812  acres 


AUSTEIA,  EUSSIA,  AND  BALKAN"  STATES   171 

in  its  possession,  the  larger  portion  having  been  sold  to  it 
by  nobles  or  large  proprietors  alarmed  by  the  agrarian  trou- 
bles of  the  preceding  few  years.  "The  latent  agitation,"  says 
the  Bank's  report,  "which  in  the  last  six  months  of  1905  de- 
generated into  acts  of  violence,  caused  a  panic  among  land- 
owners. Agitators  instigated  the  rural  population  to  aggres- 
sion. Landowners  were  driven  from  their  estates.  Plunder, 
destruction  of  livestock  and  implements,  incendiarism,  and 
the  devastation  of  forests,  to  which  the  peasants  openly 
abandoned  themselves,  together  with  their  refusal  to  work, 
rendered  the  management  of  the  estates  impossible.  .  .  .  The 
peasants  were  waiting  for  the  division  of  land  announced  by 
the  revolutionists,  and  private  investors  were  afraid  to  place 
their  capital  in  the  land."  So  the  Bank  took  over  this  enor- 
mous acreage  to  save  it  from  falling  into  the  hands  of  specu- 
lators. Between  1906  and  1910  the  Bank  subdivided  and  sold 
to  farmers  4,041,789  acres  for  $92,700,000. 

The  Bank  lends  only  to  enable  gentile  Eussian  farmers 
to  acquire  or  improve  farm  lands.  Jews  and  aliens  are  ex- 
cluded. The  farm  must  not  exceed  56.7  acres.  Loans  must 
be  secured  by  first  mortgage  on  the  property  thus  allotted  or 
bought  or  intended  to  be  improved.  They  may  equal  90  or 
even  100  per  cent  of  the  value  of  undivided  lands  to  individ- 
uals, but  for  associations  and  counties  the  limit  is  set  at  80 
or  85  per  cent.  Pour  periods  are  allowed  for  the  extinction 
of  the  debt :  13  years  by  an  annuity  of  9%  per  cent;  18  years 
by  an  annuity  of  7^  per  cent;  38  years  by  an  annuity  of  5.80 
per  cent ;  and  55%  years  by  an  annuity  of  4%  per  cent.  This 
means  that  the  interest  rate  is  four  per  cent.  The  debentures 
of  the  Bank  are  executed  by  the  Minister  of  Finance.  They 
bear  four  per  cent  interest,  and  as  they  are  quoted  above  par, 
the  bank  is  enabled  to  obtain  money  at  a  rate  slightly  lower 
than  that  charged  on  the  loans.  No  more  than  $2,575,000 
in  debentures  may  be  issued  in  any  one  year  without  the 
express  sanction  of  the  Czar. 

Although  the  Peasants'  State  Land  Bank  procures  this 
cheap  and  easy  money  for  its  borrowers,  it  has  always  en- 
countered great  difficulty  in  collecting  its  loans.    The  farmers 


172  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

seem  to  think  that  inasmuch  as  the  Government  has  taken 
such  pains  in  helping  them  to  acquire  land,  it  ought  to  go  the 
full  length  and  let  them  have  it  free.  Indeed,  the  ez-serfs 
of  the  crown  and  public  domains  appear  never  to  have  had 
any  iatention  of  paying  their  annuities.  The  defaults  were 
so  numerous,  heavy  and  long  continued  that  the  Government 
dared  not  resort  to  forcible  measures  for  fear  of  insurrec- 
tion, and  in  1907,  realizing  that  there  was  no  hope  of  recov- 
ery, it  renoimced  all  rights  to  overdue  annuities  and  charges 
and  thereby  released  the  farmers  from  a  debt  the  capitalized 
value  of  which  was  $839,820,800.  This  of  course  practically 
wiped  out  the  assets  of  the  Bank.  But  the  Eussian  Govern- 
ment is  patient  and  indulgent  vidth  the  farmers,  and  has  per- 
mitted them  to  contract  further  debts  under  its  guarantee. 
Their  outstanding  loans  at  the  Bank  now  exceed  $515,000,- 
000,  none  of  which  brings  in  any  profit,  the  institution  being 
purely  benevolent. 

The  Peasants'  State  Bank  employs  about  2,000  surveyors 
and  agricultural  experts,  and  has  also  a  special  board  with 
branches  to  act  in  conjunction  with  the  land  commissions 
with  their  more  than  5,000  officials  and  employees.  All  pur- 
chases and  parceling  of  lands  by  the  Bank  are  now  conducted 
through  the  commissions,  while  the  transactions  of  the  com- 
missions are  nearly  all  financed  by  the  Bank;  thus  all  are 
parts  of  a  grand  system.  The  land  commissions  were  estab- 
lished in  1906,  when  the  farmers  for  the  first  time  were  given 
the  unrestricted  control  of  the  land  which  had  been  allotted 
to  them.  The  commissions  were  charged  with  the  allotment 
of  lands  still  held  in  common,  on  which  the  collective  liability 
for  annuities  had  all  been  abolished  in  1905,  and  they  were 
substituted  for  the  counties  as  the  official  agents  for  tmifying 
the  detached  plots  held  by  farmers.  In  1911  the  commis- 
sions were  authorized  to  assist  any  farmer  to  readjust  his 
holdings,  no  matter  from  whom  the  title  was  derived,  and 
to  help  him  to  acquire  land  suiBcient  for  his  needs. 

The  work  carried  out  by  the  land  commissions,  with  the 
aid  of  the  Peasants'  State  Land  Bank,  during  the  first  five 
years  of  their  existence  affected  29,085,132  acres,  or  about 


AUSTEIA,  EUSSIA,  AND  BALKAN  STATES   173 

two-thirds  of  the  CTiltivated  area  of  Prussia  or  one-half  that 
of  Italy.  The  commissions  are  authorized  to  grant  small 
loans  to  farmers  whom  they  have  assisted  in  acquiring  land 
or  uniting  plots.  These  -loans  may  be  made  without  interest 
and  payable  in  equal  instalments  beginning  with  the  sixth 
year,  and  the  amount  of  each  must  not  be  over  $77.25.  They 
are  granted  to  help  pay  the  initial  expense  incurred  by  a 
farmer  in  taking  up  a  farm.  The  total  amount  thus  distrib- 
uted by  the  commissioners  from  1906  to  1911  was  $6,928,059. 

In  Finland  state  aid  is  extensively  used  for  home  coloni- 
zation. Large  tracts  bought  by  the  state  have  been  subdivided 
and  sold  to  persons  without  land,  but  the  most  common  prac- 
tice since  1900  has  been  for  the  state  to  advance  the  funds 
for  this  purpose  to  communes  and  cooperative  societies.  These 
intermediaries  between  the  state  and  the  small  holder  may 
acquire  land  by  direct  purchase  for  subdivision  and  sale,  or 
may  grant  loans  to  individuals  in  order  to  assist  them  ia 
buying  holdings. 

The  commxmes  are  required  to  organize  rural  banks  be- 
fore they  may  receive  advances  from  the  state,  and  each  com- 
mune is  made  liable  for  any  advance  its  rural  bank  receives. 
Each  bank  is  managed  by  a  board  consisting  of  three  residents, 
two  of  whom  must  be  landowners,  appointed  by  the  com- 
mimal  council.  The  cooperative  societies  which  may  receive 
advances  are  those  organized  on  the  collective-liability  basis, 
and  they  lend  only  to  members.  In  1912  there  were  303 
communal  rural  banks  and  13  cooperative  land-purchasing 
societies  operating  vdth  state  funds.  The  latter  are  steadily 
increasing  in  number  and  will  eventually  become  the  more 
numerous  because  they  may  take  back  from  a  member  a 
mortgage  up  to  nine-tenths  of  the  purchase  price  of  the  hold- 
ing, while  a  borrower  from  the  communal  banks  may  receive 
a  loan  only  up  to  one-half  the  amount  of  the  purchase  price. 

The  advances  made  by  the  state  bear  four  per  cent  inter- 
est, together  with  an  instalment  on  the  principal  sufBeient  to 
extinguish  the  debt  within  25  or  30  years.  The  banks  charge 
their  borrowers  4%  per  cent  interest,  the  difference  being 
used  for  expenses  or  profits  which  are  employed  by  the  banks 


174  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

for  the  good  of  their  comnnmes,  and  by  the  cooperative  land 
purchasing  societies  for  rebates  among  their  members.  The 
smallest  advance  of  the  state  to  a  bank  or  society  is  $965, 
and  the  largest  $46,320.  The  banks  may  not  make  loans  of 
less  than  $38.60  or  over  $386,  except  in  a  few  favored  prov- 
inces, Trhere  the  maximum  may  be  $579. 

The  Mortgage  Society  of  Pinland,  foimded  ia  1860,  is 
an  association  empowered  to  issue  guaranteed  debentures  for 
the  purpose  of  making  loans  to  members  upon  the  security  of 
unencumbered  real  estate  on  their  joint  and  several  liability. 
This  liability  is  so  regulated  that  the  properties  and  their 
owners  are  liable  on  the  debentures  only  in  proportion  to 
the  mortgages  given.  A  reserve  formed  by  small  additions 
to  the  interest  rate  on  the  loans  is  maintained  at  five  per  cent 
of  the  face  value  of  debentures  in  circulation,  in  order  to 
meet  possible  losses  and  protect  members  from  the  responsi- 
bility of  their  guaranty. 

Similar  to  the  Finnish  association  is  the  Territorial  Credit 
Establishment  for  the  Baltic  provinces  of  Livonia,  Esthonia 
and  Courland,  which  was  chartered  in  1818  by  Emperor 
Alexander  who  advanced  it  the  necessary  funds  for  its  first 
operations.  This  advance  has  been  returned  long  since.  The 
collective  liability  of  the  borrowing  members  is  limited  for 
each  to  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  prop- 
erties. 

In  Boumania  the  policy  of  expropriating  the  nobility  for 
the  benefit  of  the  peasants  was  inaugurated  in  1864.  The 
Government  paid  for  the  estates  confiscated  and  also  bore 
the  cost  of  their  subdivision  and  allotment  among  the  peas- 
ants. The  enormous  numbers  of  peasants  who  were  given 
small  holdings  left  the  nobility  and  large  proprietors  without 
the  customary  forced  labor  to  operate  the  land  which  re- 
xaained  to  them,  and  as  a  result  they  gradually  fell  in  debt 
and  were  compelled  to  mortgage  their  farms  in  order  to  raise 
money  for  living  expenses.  The  German  landschaft  system 
-was  introduced  for  this  class  by  a  law  enacted  in  1873,  and 
the  three  institutions  which  were  founded  under  that  law 
received  subsidies  from  the  state. 


AUSTRIA,  EUSSIA,  AND  BALEAN  STATES   175 

In  1908  the  Eural  Bank  was  founded  in  Eoumania  on 
lines  similar  to  the  Enssian  Peasants'  State  Bank.  The  Gov- 
ernment subscribed  one-half  of  the  $3,000,000  capital,  and  re- 
served the  right  of  designating  its  president  and  of  super- 
vising its  business  through  a  commissioner.  In  1909,  after 
the  serious  peasants'  revolt  of  1907,  the  state  extended  fur- 
ther favors  to  the  small  holders  by  providing  by  law  that 
rural  cooperative  associations  should  be  given  the  refusal  of 
all  public  lands  or  lands  of  charitable  institutions,  districts 
and  communes  which  should  be  offered  for  lease. 

In  Servia  a  bond  and_  mortgage  institution  was  founded 
by  the  Government  in  1862.  This  land  bank  is  the  depositary 
of  the  public  funds  of  the  nation  and  of  the  communes.  It 
is  managed  by  officers  appointed  by  the  Government,  and  a 
part  of  its  profits  go  into  the  national  treasury. 


CHAPTEE  XVII 

SWITZEELAND,    DENMABK,    AND    SCANDINAVIA 

Numerous  Swiss  Land-credit  Institutions. — ^Unique  Mortgage  Banks. 
— Danish  Associations  Like  German  Landsehafts. — Mortgage  As- 
sociations in  Denmark. — Mortgage  Bank  of  the  Elingdom  of  Den- 
nark. — ^Home  Colonization  Policy. — ^Landowners'  Mortgage  As- 
sociations.— Swedish  General  Mortgage  Bank. — Appropriations 
by  Swedish  Government. — State  Aid  in  Norway. — ^Work  Done 
through  Norwegian  Bank  for  Laborers'  Holdings  and  Dwellings. 

There  are  in  Switzerland  28  land-credit  institutions  be- 
longing to  the  state  or  operating  with  the  support  of  the 
state,  and  60  private  mortgage  banks,  besides  104  savings  and 
loan  banks  which  accord  real-estate  credit.  All  these  insti- 
tutions have  been  successful  in  granting  loans  for  very 
small  sums,  even  up  to  four-fifths  of  the  value  of  the  land,  at 
low  interest  rates  and  on  easy  terms.  They  are  able  to  do 
this  because  they  are  so  numerous  and  in  such  close  prox- 
imity to  borrowers  that  they  may  examine  carefully  all  appli- 
cations and  keep  watch  over  securities  and  the  use  of  the 
money  lent.  Until  1913  there  were  60  different  forms  of 
mortgages  and  considerable  variety  in  the  interest  rates.  The 
banks  perhaps  would  not  have  been  able  to  do  much  good 
had  it  not  been  for  the  fact  that  there  was  an  ample  supply 
of  local  capital.  In  that  year  a  federal  law  was  enacted  com- 
pelling all  the  banks  to  use  one  and  the  same  type  of  mort- 
gage instrument,  and  since  then  foreign  capital  has  been 
attracted  and  the  interest  rates  nearly  standardized.  They 
run  from  four  to  five  per  cent,  which  are  the  limits  fixed 
among  the  23  cantons  by  the  usury  laws. 

The  mortgage  banks  of  Switzerland  differ  from  those  of 
the  rest  of  Europe  in  that  there  is  no  correspondence  between 

176 


SWITZEELAND,   DENMAEK,   SCANDINAVIA    m 

the  debentures  and  the  loans.  The  reason  for  this  is  that 
most  of  the  Helvetian  mortgage  banks  do  all  kinds  of  bank- 
ing business  and  finance  their  real-estate  loan  transactions 
by  any  available  money  on  hand.  The  issue  of  debentures  or 
bondSj  however,  is  usually  limited  to  ten  or  fifteen  times  the 
capital  stock.  All  loans  are  made  in  cash,  the  debentures 
being  issued  and  disposed  of  directly  by  the  banks  according 
to  their  needs.  State  supervision  is  not  exercised  to  the  same 
extent  by  all  the  cantons,  but  in  many  it  is  so  pronounced 
that  the  mortgage  banks  are  public  or  semi-public  institu- 
tions. 

The  Mortgage  Bank  of  Berne,  founded  in  1846  and  re- 
modeled in  1875,  was  given  $1,400,000  for  its  initial  capital 
by  the  canton,  which  has  also  furnished  other  sources  of 
revenue.  It  has  been  made  the  depositary  of  public  funds 
and  it  administers  the  public  debt  and  financial  affairs  of 
the  canton. '  It  may  make  first-mortgage  loans  on  lands  situ- 
ated vrithin  the  canton  up  to  two-thirds  of  their  value,  lend 
upon  such  securities,  and  receive  deposits.  But  the  loans  are 
not  made  directly  by  the  Bank.  The  borrower  must  apply 
through  the  commune  which  has  jurisdiction  over  the  locality 
in.  which  his  property  lies.  Each  commune  guarantees  all 
loans  which  it  approves,  but  its  liability  extends  only  to  the 
estimated  value  of  the  mortgaged  property,  and  it  cannot  be 
called  upon  to  pay  any  more  than  the  amount  of  the  defi- 
ciency remaining  after  the  property  has  been  sold  on  execu- 
tion. But  it  is  not  responsible  for  depreciation  in  the  prop- 
erty occurring  after  the  loan  has  been  granted.  The  canton 
guarantees  aU  engagements  of  the  Bank  not  covered  by  its 
assets.  The  Bank  must  give  the  preference  to  small  loans. 
The  largest  allowed  is  $10,000.  Eepayment  is  made  by  an- 
nuities, which  (including  interest)  must  not  exceed  six  per 
cent  a  year.  The  interest  cannot  be  one-fourth  of  one  per  cent 
over  the  highest  rate  for  deposits.  The  mortgages  do  not 
have  to  be  refiled  every  ten  years  as  provided  in  the  general 
laws. 

In  the  canton  of  Vaud  the  Government  purchased  11,000 
of  the  19,500  shares  issued  by  the  Mortgage  Bank  of  Vaud 


178  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

for  $110,000,  and  guarantees  a  four  per  cent  dividend.  The 
Vaud  Bank  is  authorized  to  use  in  its  business  the  deposits  of 
the  government  savings  bank  and  the  government  insurance 
society.  Its  business  is  confined  to  making  first-mortgage 
loans  up  to  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  lands  and  buildings 
within  the  canton;  to  lending  on  the  security  of  such  mort- 
gages or  debentures  secured  by  such  mortgages ;  and  to  invest- 
ing its  assets  in  certain  other  kinds  of  bankable  paper.  The 
shortest  mortgage  loan  is  five  years,  and  the  smallest  $60. 
Loans  repayable  by  annuities  are  preferred,  and  they  may  run 
from  nine  to  57  years. 

Stockholders  of  the  Mortgage  Bank  of  Vand  have  two 
votes  for  every  ten  shares  up  to  50,  four  for  the  next  50 
Tip  to  100,  and  one  for  each  additional  100  shares.  At  their 
biennial  meeting  they  elect  ten  members  of  the  board  of 
directors,  two  auditors  and  two  secretaries.  The  cantonal 
council  of  state  appoints  the  president  and  the  ten  other 
members  of  the  board  of  directors,  all  of  whom  must  be 
stockholders.  It  also  appoints  from  among  the  public  ofB.- 
cials  a  secretary  for  the  board  of  directors  and  four  stock- 
holders to  act  with  the  president  as  the  committee  of  super- 
vision, the  latter  chosen  out  of  12  named  by  the  board  of 
directors.  Likewise,  it  appoints  a  managing  committee  of 
a  chairman  and  two  directors,  chosen  from  a  list  of  nine 
nominees  presented  by  the  board  of  directors.  It  will  be  seen 
that  the  state  thus  has  complete  control  of  the  Mortgage 
Bank  of  Vaud. 

The  Land  Credit  Bank  of  Geneva  was  supplied  at  its 
foundation  with  a  capital  contributed  by  all  the  48  com- 
munes of  the  canton,  and  it  is  managed  by  a  board  of  direc- 
tors composed  of  members  of  the  cantonal  and  communal 
councils.  The  Mortgage  Bank  of  St.  Gall,  though  a  private 
joint-stock  company,  was  created  by  the  initiative  and  is 
operated  under  the  guaranty  of  the  cantonal  government. 
The  canton  owns  one-fourth  of  the  capital  stock  of  the  Mort- 
gage Bank  of  Fribourg,  and  supervises  its  management 
through  a  committee  composed  of  the  financial  director  of  the 
canton,  two  members  named  by  the  council  of  state,  and  12 


SWITZERLAND,   DENMARK,   SCANDINAVIA    17? 

chosen  by  the  stockholders.  This  bank  offers  a  peculiar  ser- 
yiee  not  found  elsewhere.  If  the  debtor  of  a  third  person 
will  make  a  contract,  secured  by  real  estate,  to  pay  to  the 
bank  annuities  for  a  number  of  years  to  be  agreed  upon,  the 
bank  will  undertake  to  pay  the  creditor  his  interest  and  capi- 
talize the  remaining  portion  of  the  annuities  to  pay  off  the 
principal  at  maturity. 

In  Denmark  there  are  14  land-credit  associations,  pat- 
terned after  the  new  German  landschafts,  but  differing  from 
them  in  a  few  particulars.  The  Danish  landschafts  lend  on 
both  rural  and  urban  real  estate,  and  may  grant  straight 
loans  even  for  60  years  without  amortization,  provided  they 
do  not  exceed  one-third  of  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  property. 
They  may  issue  their  debentures  in  such  a  way  that  mem- 
bers are  liable  only  for  the  series  emitted  during  the  period 
in  which  they  were  admitted.  The  liability  is  further  re- 
stricted in  that  it  extends  to  the  full  amount  of  the  debenture 
if  the  loan  for  which  it  was  exchanged  equals  three-fifths  of 
the  estimated  value  of  the  mortgaged  property,  but  is  corre- 
spondingly less  if  tie  loan  is  smaller  than  that  fraction. 
Apart  from  these  differences  there  is  little  to  distinguish 
the  Danish  landschafts  from  the  German  type.  Their 
debentures  are  free  from  stamp  taxes  and  are  a  lawful  in- 
vestment for  public  and  trustee  funds,  while  their  loans  may 
be  collected  by  summary  process.  The  associations  in  ex- 
istence were  all  organized  shortly  after  the  law  which  governs 
them  was  enacted  in  1850.  Since  1861  new  associations  can 
be  created  only  by  special  acts.  At  the  end  of  1912  the  total 
of  the  outstanding  loans  was  $440,860,000,  with  a  maturity 
of  60  to  70  years.  The  debentures  in  which  they  were  made 
bore  four  and  4%  per  cent  interest. 

Similar  to  the  land-credit  associations  are  nine  other 
Danish  landschafts  called  mortgage  associations,  which  were 
brought  into  existence  by  a  law  of  1897  for  the  exclusive 
purpose  of  extending  credit  on  second  mortgage.  These 
associations  grant  25-  to  30-year  loans  for  small  amounts  up 
to  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  property.  They 
also  lend  on  both  rural  and  urban  property,  but  although 


180  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

their  debentures  are  highly  privileged,  they  have  been  able 
to  raise  funds  for  only  $27,604,000  of  loans.  The  total 
amount  of  the  farm  loans  granted  by  the  23  Danish  land- 
Bchafts  is  estimated  at  $233,160,000. 

In  1906  the  Mortgage  Bank  of  the  Kingdom  of  Denmark 
was  founded  with  a  capital  of  $5,360,000  advanced  by  the 
state  at  three  per  cent  interest,  to  serve  as  a  central  institution 
for  the  landschafts  and  also  to  assist  the  state  in  the  work 
of  providing  small  holdings  for  homeseekers.  The  Bank 
buys  the  debentures  of  the  landschafts  and  the  state-guaran- 
teed bonds  of  the  small  holders  and  issues  its  own  bonds  upon 
their  security.  So  far  it  has  been  able  to  dispose  of  only 
$10,720,000  of  these  debentures  at  three  and  one-half  and 
four  per  cent. 

The  home  colonization  policy  of  Denmark  was  inaugu- 
rated in  1899  by  the  state's  voting  an  annual  appropriation  of 
$536,000  to  be  lent  to  small  holders.  In  1904  the  annual 
amount  was  raised  to  $804,000  and  in  1909  to  $1,720,000. 
Any  unused  portion  of  one  year's  appropriation  is  accumulated 
for  subsequent  years.  Any  able-bodied  Dane  of  good  repu- 
tation between  25  and  50  years  of  age  may  now  call  on 
the  state  to  help  him  acquire  a  rural  homestead  of  a  value 
not  exceeding  $1,742,  including  cost  of  buildings,  livestock 
and  implements.  In  exceptional  cases  the  value  may  be 
$2,144.  If  the  applicant  can  show  that  he  has  one-tenth  of 
the  value  in  ready  cash,  the  state  vdll  lend  the  balance  at 
three  per  cent  on  a  first  mortgage  to  be  repaid  at  long  term 
by  instalments, .  beginniag  in  the  sixth  year.  This  business 
is  directed  and  supervised  by  district  laborers'  holdings  com- 
missions, each  composed  of  three  members,  one  of  whom, 
acting  as  president,  is  appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Agricul- 
ture, while  the  other  two  are  elected  by  a  body  consisting  of 
two  delegates  from  each  commxine  in  the  district.  The  com- 
missioners, who  are  allowed  only  very  small  compensation, 
are  assisted  by  the  municipal  authorities.  No  landovmer, 
however,  can  be  expropriated,  in  order  to  create  small  hold- 
ings, because  the  Danish  constitution  makes  private  property 
inviolable  except  to  the  right  of  eminent  domain.    At  the  end 


SWITZEELAND,   DENMAEK,   SCANDINAVIA    181 

of  1911  the  state  had  established  5,777  homesteaders  with  the 
aid  of  $6,809,919  in  loans. 

In  Sweden  landowners'  mortgage  associations  were  the 
first  institutions  especially  created  there  to  accord  real-estate 
credit  for  agriculture.  The  oldest  of  these  was  formed  in 
1831  and  the  latest  in  1861.  There  are  now  ten  of  them,  and 
each  has  a  definite  territory,  generally  embracing  several  prov- 
inces. 

These  associations  are  not  entirely  agricultural  or  com- 
posed exclusively  of  borrowers.  Any  resident  of  the  terri- 
tory owning  land  of  the  value  of  $1,125  free  and  clear  of  all 
encumbrances  may  become  a  member  by  making  the  contri- 
butions prescribed  by  the  by-laws.  They  are  purely  private 
concerns,  the  supervision  of  the  Government  beiag  confined 
to  inspection  and  the  approval  of  the  articles  of  agreement  and 
amendments  thereto.  In  the  smallest  association  allowed  the 
members'  properties  must  have  a  combined  value  of  at  least 
$1,125,000. 

The  minimum  loan  is  $134  and  the  highest  rate  of  in- 
terest that  may  be  charged  is  sis  per  cent,  plus  a  percentage 
for  expenses.  Arrears  are  charged  a  penal  rate  of  12  per 
cent.  First  mortgages  not  exceeding  half  the  value  of  the 
land  exclusive  of  buildings  and  forests  are  always  required. 
At  present  loans  up  to  this  maximum  are  granted  for  28 
years  on  an  annuity  of  six  per  cent,  and  on  an  annuity  of  4:5 
per  cent  for  about  56  years.  Loans  not  repayable  by  annuities 
or  instalments  may  be  granted  up  to  one-third  the  value  of 
the  land  for  25  years  at  an  interest  rate  of  four  per  cent.  The 
charge  for  expenses  is  now  one-twentieth  of  the  principal. 
As  the  associations  have  no  shares  or  capital  stock,  no  divi- 
dends are  distributed.  The  profits  are  placed  in  the  reserve 
imtil  this  fund  reaches  a  certain  amount,  when  they  may  be 
used  to  lower  the  interest  rate  to  borrowers.  The  reserve 
fund  now  equals  4.61  per  cent  of  the  outstanding  loans. 

Formerly  these  associations  were  independent  of  one  an- 
other and  each  financed  itself  by  issuing  debentures.  This 
brought  about  competition  and  the  debentures  were  fre- 
quently sold  below  par.     Finally,  after  the  financial  crisis 


183  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

following  the  bad  crops  of  1857-9,  sales  ceased  entirely,  ia 
spite  of  low  quotations,  and  members  were  unable  to  get 
further  loans  or  extensions.  The  Government  decided  to 
remedy  these  troubles  and  prevent  their  recurrence  by  uniting 
the  associations  with  a  central  institution  to  be  controlled  and 
aided  by  the  state. 

This  institution,  called  the  Swedish  General  Mortgage 
Bank,  was  founded  in  1861  with  an  endowment  of  $2,144,- 
000  of  unconvertible  state  bonds.  The  Bank  is  managed  by 
a  council  composed  of  a  president  appointed  by  the  King,  a 
vice-president  appointed  by  the  parliamentary  committee  on 
the  public  debt,  and  three  delegates  elected  by  the  associa- 
tions. The  council  is  subject  to  a  board  of  five  supervisors, 
one  of  whom  is  appointed  by  the  parliamentary  committee  on 
the  public  debt  and  the  others  by  the  associations.  The  by- 
laws of  the  Bank,  made  with  the  sanction  of  the  king,  cannot 
be  altered  without  the  consent  of  Parliament.  In  1890,  when 
the  rules  and  regulations  which  now  govern  the  Bank  and 
the  associations  were  adopted,  the  state  gave  the  Bank  a  fur- 
ther subsidy  of  $8,040,000  in  non-redeemable  five  per  cent 
government  bonds,  for  converting  outstanding  debentures  of 
the  associations  issued  below  par.  This  subsidy  may  be  used 
for  loans  if  the  Bank  should  have  no  other  funds,  but  in  that 
case  the  amount  so  employed  must  be  immediately  covered 
by  an  issue  of  debentures. 

,  Membership  in  this  Bank  is  open  only  to  the  ten  land- 
owners' associations  or  others  which  may  be  formed  of  the 
same  kind.  They  are  jointly  and  severally  liable  for  all  debts 
of  the  bank.  The  liability  is  proportioned  for  each  associa- 
tion to  the  amount  unpaid  on  the  loans  it  has  received;  the 
TniTiimnTTi  liability  is  $268,000.  When  the  Bank  first  opened, 
it  absorbed  the  loans  of  the  National  Loan  Bank  which  was 
dissolved,  but  now  its  business  is  confined  to'  making  loans 
to  the  affiliated  associations  and  it  has  an  exclusive  monopoly 
of  issuing  debentures  payable  to  bearer  and  secured  by  real 
estate. 

The  lowest  rate  at  which  the  Swedish  General  Mortgage 
Bank  may  lend  to  the  associations  is  3.5  per  cent.    At  the  end 


SWITZEELAND,   DENMAEK,   SCANDINAVIA    183 

of  1913  its  debentures  in  circulation  amounted  to  $79,301,- 
987,  and  loans  to  the  associations  to  $80,192,903.  Like  the 
associations  the  Bank  has  no  share  capital  and  pays  no  divi- 
dends, all  profits  being  placed  in  the  reserve  or  used  for  re- 
ducing the  charges  to  borrowers.  The  loans  of  the  ten  asso- 
ciations to  members  amounted  in  the  same  year  to  $74,989,- 
348 ;  they  were  secured  by  first  mortgages  on  properties,  prac- 
tically all  agricultural,  valued  at  $235,161,659,  and  by  the 
reserves  and  the  joint  and  several  liability  of  the  individual 
members.  As  the  total  mortgage  debt  on  rural  lands  in 
Sweden  was  estimated  at  $536,605,784  in  1910,  this  system 
holds  a  portion  relatively  small  but  suflBciently  large  to  have 
a  salutary  effect  upon  interest  rates.  All  loans  made  by  the 
Bank  to  the  associations  or  by  the  latter  to  members  may  be 
recalled  after  ten  years.-  Members  may  pay  in  advance  but 
only  when  the  association  can  immediately  find  a  profitable 
investment  for  such  prepayments. 

The  landowners'  mortgage  associations  rarely  grant  loans 
of  the  minimum  size  allowed.  Their  members  are  mostly  nobles 
or  owners  of  large  estates.  As  in  the  case  of  the  German 
landsehafts,  from  which  it  was  copied,  this  Swedish  plan 
of  according  credit  upon  the  liability  of  groups  of  borrowers 
has  not  proved  of  much  use  to  small  farmers.  The  credit 
needs  of  this  class  are  taken  care  of  in  Sweden  by  loans  made 
from  public  funds  specially  appropriated  for  that  purpose. 
The  first  of  these  funds  was  created  in  1904  for  building 
houses  for  laborers  and  enabling  them  to  acquire  small  hold- 
ings in  the  country.  The  maximum  loan  allowed  is  $2,144 
for  purchasing  a  plot  with  no  building  upon  it,  and  $1,883 
for  land  with  buildings  standing.  Bach  loan  is  divided  into 
two  parts,  the  first  half  being  repayable  by  an  annuity  of 
sis  per  cent  in  28  years,  the  second  being  a  straight  loan  at 
3.6  per  cent  per  annum.  Loans  must  be  secured  by  mortgages 
which  may  not  exceed  five-sixths,  but  are  generally  no  more 
than  one-half,  the  value  of  the  land.  The  Government  re- 
cently appropriated  $964,800  for  facilitating  this  work,  espe- 
cially for  buying  and  cutting  up  large  tracts  of  land.  Inter- 
est on  loans  out  of  this  fund  is  4  per  cent. 


184  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

The  Swedish  Government  also  appropriates  $268,000  an- 
nually for  draining  and  preparing  newly  cleared  lands  for 
cultivation.  The  only  maximum  set  for  loans  out  of  this 
fund  is  that  they  may  not  exceed  the  amount  of  the  expendi- 
ture plus  70  per  cent  of  the  resulting  increase  in  the  value  of 
the  land.  No  interest  is  charged  for  the  first  three  years. 
After  that  3.6  per  cent  is  charged  up  to  the  seventh  year,  and 
then  an  annuity  of  6  per  cent  \mtil  the  debt  is  extinguished. 
Similar  to  this  fund  is  the  annual  appropriation  of  $80,400 
for  clearing  lands  in  Norrland.  Loans  from  the  Norrland 
fund  may  not  exceed  $134  plus  the  cost  of  clearing  the  land. 
They  bear  three  per  cent  interest  after  the  second  year  and 
must  be  repaid  within  ten  years.  Excepting  the  appropria- 
tions for  drainage,  all  loans  from  these  funds  are  made 
through  the  rural  cooperative  associations,  the  rural  people's 
banks  and  other  disinterested  intermediaries,  who  are  in- 
structed to  accept  no  applications  but  those  of  temperate  and 
industrious  persons,  male  or  female,  between  21  and  50 
years  of  age. 

The  Government  of  Norway  tentatively  began  to  assist 
the  movement  back  to  the  soil  in  1834  and  adopted  a  grand 
programme  for  that  purpose  in  1903.  The  prime  object  was 
to  supply  the  large  landholders  with  the  labor  of  which  they 
were  in  great  need,  and  it  was  thought  that  this  object  could 
be  best  accomplished  in  a  permanent  way  by  helping  each 
laborer  to  acquire  a  small  homestead  on  which  his  family 
might  live  in  comfort  by  means  of  the  crops  and  their  wages. 

The  programme  of  state  aid  is  being  carried  out  through 
the  Norwegian  Bank  for  Laborers'  Holdings  and  Dwellings, 
founded  in  1903  with  a  capital  of  $2,680,000  contributed  by 
the  Government.  This  institution  is  managed  by  the  officers 
of  the  Norwegian  Land  Mortgage  Bank  organized  in  1851, 
and  is  supervised  by  the  Minister  of  Finance.  These  officers 
are  assisted  by  local  committees  of  labor,  appointed  by  the 
communal  council  in  every  commune  in  which  the  bank  does 
business,  out  of  electors  equally  divided  between  laborers  and 
landowners. 

The  state  draws  five  per  cent  interest  per  annum  on  the 


SWITZEELAND,   DEISTMAEK,   SCANDIFAVIA   185 

capital,  but  makes  good  any  losses  incuired.  The  Bank  may 
issue  debentures  payable  to  bearer  whenever  its  own  funds 
become  insufficient.  These  bonds  are  signed  by  the  Minister 
of  Finance  and  are  guaranteed  by  the  state.  They  run  from 
30  to  80  years  and  are  recallable  at  the  will  of  the  Bank. 
The  total  in.  circulation  must  never  exceed  six  times  the  capi- 
tal stock.  Another  privilege  is  that  the  Bank  may  sell  at 
auction  any  mortgaged  property,  in  case  of  default  after  de- 
mand, simply  by  publishing  a  notice  for  six  weeks  in  the  offi- 
cial newspaper  and  the  further  notice  provided  by  law  on 
judicial  sales.  No  judgment  or  action  by  the  courts  is  re- 
quired. 

The  loans  of  the  Norwegian  Bank  for  Laborers'  Holdings 
and  Dwellings  are  granted  to  poor  persons,  male  or  female, 
either  for  the  purchase  of  small  farms  or  for  erecting,  com- 
pleting or  purchasing  dwellings.  A  person  is  considered 
poor  if  his  assets  are  less  than  $402.  A  small  farm  is  50 
acres  of  land,  cultivated  or  not,  or  at  most  200  acres  of  culti- 
vated land  the  value  of  which  does  not  exceed  $804.  If  the 
application  of  such  a  person  is  approved  by  the  committee  of 
labor  of  the  commune  which  he  inhabits,  he  may  obtain  a 
loan  from  the  Bank  for  buying  such  a  small  farm  and  for 
erecting  the  necessary  buildings  on  it.  The  amount  must  not 
exceed  nine-tenths  of  the  actual  price  increased  by  the  esti- 
mated value  of  the  improvements.  The  interest  rate  is  3.5  per 
cent.  The  principal  is  repaid  in  semi-annual  instalments  be- 
ginning in  the  sixth  year  of  the  loan  and  running  for  42  years. 
The  security  in  all  eases  must  be  a  first  mortgage  guaranteed 
by  the  commune.  These  loans  may  be  made  directly  to  the 
applicant,  or  the  Bank  may  advance  money  to  the  commune 
for  the  purchase  of  tracts  to  be  divided  and  sold  on  mortgage 
to  poor  persons. 

Loans  for  erecting,  completing  or  improving  dwellings 
also  may  be  made  directly  or  to  the  communes  or  to  societies 
organized  for  building  such  houses.  These  building  loans 
draw  four  per  cent  interest,  and  the  repayment  of  the  capital 
begins  after  the  second  year  and  runs  for  28  years.  The 
terms  imposed  for  these  loans  have  some  points  of  difference 


186  EURAL   CREDITS 

depending  on  whether  the  house  is  to  be  erected  in  the  town 
or  in  the  country.  For  country  building  the  requirements  ex- 
acted are  about  the  same  as  those  for  the  purchase  of  small 
farms,  with  the  exception  that  the  plot  cannot  exceed  50 
acres.  The  loan  is  paid  to  the  contractor  in  instalments  as 
the  work  on  the  building  progresses.  The  total  amount  up 
to  which  a  rural  commune  may  obligate  itseK  in  guarantee- 
ing loans  at  the  Bank  is  $40,200.  The  number  of  rural  hold- 
ings created  by  loans  from  the  Bank  down  to  1913  was 
11,579. 


CHAPTER  XVIII 

LAND    CREDIT    OUTSIDB    OF    ETJEOPE 

Land-credit  Institutions  in  Egypt. — ^Land-credit  System  of  Japan. — 
Agricultural  Bank  of  the  Philippines. — State  Banks  of  Australia. 
— Queensland  Agricultural  Bank. — State  Aid  for  Home  Coloniza- 
tion in  New  Zealand. — Mexican  Land  Mortgage  Banks  and  Pro- 
motion Banks. — Three  Land-credit  Institutions  in  Argentine  Re- 
public.— Early  and  Successful  Laud  Credit  in  Chile. — Banco  Hi- 
potecario  del  Uruguay. — Costa  Eica  's  State  Land-mortgage  Bank.. 
— Territorial  Bank  of  Cuba. — ^Development  in  Europe  and 
America  of  Loans  on  Life  Insurance  Policies. 

The  highest  estimate  of  the  value  of  real  estate  in  Egypt 
is  five  billions,  and  the  lowest,  two  billions  of  dollars.  The 
mortgage  indebtedness  is  about  $243,000,000,  or  at  most  not 
much  over  one-twentieth  of  the  highest  estimated  value  of 
the  land;  and  since  the  interest  rate  thereon  varies  from  5^4 
to  7  per  cent,  the  landowners  have  no  difficulty  in  carrying 
this  burden,  because  the  land  itself  yields  six  to  nine  per 
cent  annually,  and  nowhere  is  encumbered  to  over  60  per 
cent  of  its  value.  About  $40,600,000  of  this  indebtedness 
is  held  by  private  persons  and  insurance  companies,  and 
the  rest  by  the  five  land-credit  institutions  now  existing  in 
Egypt. 

Some  features  are  worthy  of  notice  iu  two  of  these  institu- 
tions, the  Credit  Poncier  Egyptien  (Egyptian  Land  Credit 
Company)  and  the  Agricultural  Bank  of  Egypt.  The  former  is 
a  private  joint-stock  company  operating  without  any  special 
privileges.  Its  main  object  is  to  grant  long-term  loans  se- 
cured by  first  mortgage,  running  from  five  to  50  years  and 
repayable  by  periodical  instalments.  In  appraising  land  for 
security  it  places  its  valuation  at  50  per  cent  of  the  actual 
value  and  allows  credit  only  up  to  ecTper  cent  of  that  valua- 

187       ■  7 


188  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

tion.  This  wide  margia  makes  its  debentures  so  safe  and  sale- 
able that  it  is  able  to  grant  loans  at  the  lowest  rate  prevailing 
in  Egypt.  The  last  debentures  issued  bore  four  per  cent  in- 
terest, but  this  does  not  indicate  the  true  cost  of  raising 
money  for  its  operations,  because  as  a  general  practice  it 
issues  its  debentures  below  par  so  as  .to  give  the  holder  a 
premium  at  maturity.  At  the  beginning  of  1913  the  out- 
standing debentures  amounted  to  $116,975,436.  Dividends 
have  never  been  under  9%  per  cent  a  year.  For  the  last  four 
years  they  have  been  26  per  cent  on  ordinary  shares  and  over 
500  per  cent  on  founders'  shares.  The  company  serves  large 
and  medium-sized  landowners. 

The  second  institution  mentioned,  the  Agricultural  Bank 
of  Egypt,  is  especially  designed  for  the  small  proprietor. 
Mne-tenths  of  the  population  of  Egypt  is  agricultural,  and 
the  holdings  and  credit  needs  of  the  majority  of  them  are  too 
small  to  he  considered  by  other  Egyptian  banks.  The  first 
remedy  devised  for  supplying  the  lack  of  credit  facilities  was 
put  in  operation  in  1894,  when  the  Government  bought  cot- 
ton seed  and  sold  it  to  the  growers  on  time;  this  has  been 
done  on  various  occasions  since.  The  next  move  was  to  re- 
quire the  Credit  Foncier  Egyptien  to  lower  the  minimum  of 
its  loans  to  $500,  but  as  the  average  loan  of  the  Egyptian 
farmer  is  below  $150,  this  did  not  do  much  good.  The  Na- 
tional Bank  of  Egypt,  however,  opened  an  agricultural  sec- 
tion soon  after  its  establishment  in  1898,  and  began  to  grant 
loans  in  sums  of  $100  and  under,  payable  in  five  annual  in- 
stalments. The  Bank's  business  of  this  kind  grew  so  rapidly 
in  volume,  absorbed  so  much  of  its  assets,  and  showed  such 
a  large  unsatisfied  demand  for  loans  that  in  1902  the  Govern- 
ment brought  into  existence  the  Agricultural  Bank  to  attend 
exclusively  to  the  needs  of  the  small  farmers,  and  transferred 
all  outstanding  agricultural  loans  of  the  National  Bank  of 
Egypt  to  the  new  institution. 

The  Agricultural  Bank  of  Egypt  is  a  private  joiut-stock 
company,  but  it  is  supported  and  controlled  by  the  state. 
About  one-third  of  its  shares  are  owned  by  the  National  Bank, 
which  stands  in  close  relations  with  the  Government.     The 


LAND    CEE-DIT    OUTSIDE    OF   EUEOPE      189 

president  of  the  board  of  management  is  the  governor  of  the 
National  Bank.  This  board  consists  of  seven  members,  three 
of  whom  are  chosen  from  among  the  directors  of  the  National 
Bank.  Government  commissioners  audit  the  accounts  of  the 
Agricultural  Bank  and  supervise  its  affairs.  The  Govern- 
ment guarantees  3  per  cent  dividends  on  its  stock  and  also 
the  repayment  of  its  debentures  whenever  this  is  necessary 
in  order  to  obtain  money  at  fair  interest  rates.  The  tax  col- 
lectors collect  and  remit  the  payments  on  loans,  the  Bank 
giving  them  a  one-half  of  one  per  cent  commission  for  this 
work. 

The  Agricultural  Bank  of  Egypt  grants  both  real  and 
personal  credit.  Loans  not  exceeding  $98.86  and  running 
for  15  months  or  less  may  be  granted  on  personal  security. 
Loans  over  that  amount  must  be  secured  by  first  mortgages 
on  real  estate  worth  at  least  double  the  amount  of  the  loan. 
The  maximum  size  of  the  loans  is  $1,483.90  and  the  greatest 
length  5y2  years.  They  are  usually  repayable  by  instalments. 
The  highest  interest  which  may  be  charged  is  nine  per  cent 
per  annum.  The  maximum  for  all  loans,  new  and  old,  must 
be  reduced  to  eight  per  cent  when  the  total  of  the  loans 
amounts  at  the  end  of  the  previous  year  to  $34,601,000.  In 
1911  the  Bank  had  granted  loans  to  over  350,000  small 
farmers.  The  average  size  of  the  personal  loans  was  about 
$60,  and  of  the  real-estate  loans  $170.  The  latter  constitute 
most  of  the  business  of  the  bank. 

In  Japan  the  land-credit  system  comprises  the  Nippon 
Kwango  Gioko,  a  central  land-credit  bank  for  making  large 
loans  all  over  the  country,  and  the  Noko  Ginko,  land-credit 
banks  of  a  local  character,  of  which  there  are  46,  or  one  in 
each  prefecture.  Besides  these  institutions  there  is  the  Co- 
lonial Bank  for  Hokkaido,  which  extends  its  operations  into 
the  Japanese  portion  of  the  island  of  Saghalien,  while  the 
Taiwan  Bank  talses  care  of  the  agricultural  needs  of  For- 
mosa, and  the  Chosen  Bank  and  the  Oriental  Colonization 
Company  of  those  of  Korea. 

AU  these  banks  were  chartered  by  special  acts  or  decrees, 
and  the  rules  and  regulations  governing  them  are  not  all 


190  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

alike.  The  Kwango  Ginko  or  Central  Bank  was  organized  in 
1896.  It  is  authorized  to  make  loans  secured  by  first  mort- 
gage on  real  estate,  repayable  by  annuities  within  50  years, 
and  loans  similarly  secured  or  on  fishery  rights  to  be  paid  in 
lump  within  five  years.  The  latter  must  never  exceed  in  total 
amount  one-tenth  of  the  former.  Moreover,  loans  secured  by 
urban  properties  must  never  exceed  one-half  of  the  Bank's 
paid-in  capital.  Long-term  loans  repayable  by  annuities  may 
be  made  to  the  Koko  Ginko  banks  on  the  security  of  mort- 
gages taken  by  them,  and  without  mortgage  security  to  mu- 
nicipalities, public  corporations,  farm  land  adjustment  asso- 
ciations, cooperative  societies,  fishery  and  forestry  societies 
and  their  federations.  The  Bank  may  also  guarantee  the 
bonds  of  the  Noko  Ginko  banks. 

In  addition  to  the  foregoing  powers  the  Central  Bank 
may  buy  the  bonds  issued  by  the  Noko  Ginko  and,  with  its 
surplus  funds,  the  bonds  of  the  Imperial  Government,  receive 
bullion  and  negotiable  instruments  for  safekeeping,  and  ac- 
cept deposits  up  to  the  amount  of  its  paid-in  capital.  Loans 
may  not  be  granted  on  the  security  of  schools,  hospitals,  sani- 
tariums, theaters,  mines,  quarries,  swamps,  or  mineral 
springs.  The  properties  used  for  security  must  be  such  that 
the  Bank  may  acquire  a  first  lien  on  their  titles  and  that 
their  revenues  will  equal  the  annuities  or  annual  instalments 
to  be  paid  on  the  loans.  The  loan  must  never  exceed  in 
amount  two-thirds  of  the  value  of  its  security;  on  buildings 
the  loan  may  be  only  one-half  of  the  value  and  the  buildiags 
must  be  insured  in  favor  of  the  Bank. 

The  interest  rate  on  loans  is  determined  by  the  Miaister 
of  Finance.  The  maximum  is  now  eight  per  cent.  The  an- 
nuities or  annual  instalments  of  a  loan  must  be  level  or  equal 
for  all  the  years  of  the  term.  The  debentures  issued  by  the 
Bank  have  no  fixed  maturity  but  are  redeemed  two  or  more 
times  a  year  by  drawings,  up  to  the  amounts  paid  in  or 
which  should  have  been  paid  in  on  the  loans.  The  total  of 
debentures  in  circulation  must  never  exceed  the  live  out- 
standing loans,  and  if  borrowers  make  advance  payments,  a 
corresponding  amount  of  debentures  must  be  withdrawn  forth- 


LAND   CEEDIT   OUTSIDE   OF  EUROPE      191 

with  by  redemption  or  purchase.  The  debentures  may  be 
issued  to  be  redeemed  with  premiums  and  prizes. 

The  Imperial  Government  guaranteed  5  per  cent  divi- 
dends on  the  capital  stock  of  the  Nippon  Kwango  Ginko  dur- 
ing the  first  ten  years.  This  guaranty  is  no  longer  continued, 
but  the  Bank  is  exempted  from  registration  and  stamp  duties, 
enjoys  various  other  immunities,  is  subject  to  the  control  of 
two  public  supervisors,  and  is  used  as  the  agent  for  distribu- 
ting the  money  which  the  Government  provides  for  cheap 
loans  to  the  Noko  Ginko,  the  Colonial  Bank  of  Hokkaido, 
the  farm-land  adjustment,  cooperative,  forestry  and  fishery 
societies.  This  money  now  comes  from  the  postal  savings 
banks. 

In  1913  the  Nippon  Kwango  Ginko  had  a  capital  of 
$4,980,000,  of  which  $3,112,500  had  been  paid  in.  The 
outstanding  loans,  including  the  bonds  of  the  Noko  Ginko 
guaranteed  by  the  Bank,  amounted  to  $72,912,076,  and  the 
debentures  in  circulation  to  $64,531,225.  The  profits  were 
33  per  cent  of  the  paid-in  capital  after  setting  aside  the  usual 
eight  per  cent  for  the  reserve  and  an  additional  two  per  cent 
into  a  fund  maintained  for  steadying  the  dividends. 

The  Noko  Ginko,  or  local  prefectural  land-credit  banks, 
were  established  by  a  law  enacted  in  1896,  and  all  46  banking 
institutions  were  brought  into  existence  within  a  few  years 
thereafter,  each  with  a  capital  of  $149,400  or  more.  They 
may  make  long-time  reducible  loans  for  30  years  and  term 
loans  for  five  years  for  the  same  purposes,  upon  the  same 
kind  of  security  and  conditions,  and  to  the  same  classes  of 
borrowers  allowed  to  the  central  mortgage  bank.  The  coop- 
erative societies,  to  which  they  may  grant  unsecured  loans, 
must  be  composed  of  at  least  20  members  with  joint  and 
several  liability.  These  local  banks  also  may  receive  bullion 
and  negotiable  instruments  for  safekeeping  and  accept  de- 
posits up  to  the  amount  of  their  paid-in  capital.  No  limit  is 
set  for  the  deposits  which  may  be  taken  in  gold.  They  may 
also  buy  negotiable  instruments  and  securities  of  other  banks 
under  regulations  similar  to  those  prescribed  for  the  Central 
Bank.     Bonds  may  be  issued  and  put  in  circulation  up  to 


192  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

five  times  their  paid-in  capital,  but  they  may  not  be  sold 
with  a  premium  or  prizes.  The  only  relation  of  the  'Ndko 
Ginko  with  the  Central  Bank  is  that  the  latter  institution 
may  guarantee  and  sell  the  bonds  of  the  locals  and  advance 
them  fimds  in  case  of  necessity. 

The  Imperial  Government  appropriated  $4,980,000  as  a 
subsidy  for  the  Noko  Ginko  banks.  This  sum  was  allotted 
among  the  prefectures  at  the  rate  of  70  yen  ($34.86)  for  every 
100  cho  (245  acres),  and  was  used  by  the  prefectures  for  buy- 
ing shares  in  the  banks.  No  dividends  were  allowed  on  the 
shares  so  acquired  for  the  first  five  years,  and  after  that  the 
dividends  thereon  were  put  into  the  reserves  by  order  of  a 
decree  which  required  them  to  be  so  set  aside  for  15  years. 
The  banks  are  supervised  by  high  prefectural  ofScers. 

At  the  beginning  of  1912  the  capital  of  the  46  Noko 
Ginko  banks  was  $17,166,060,  of  which  $15,120,260  was  paid 
up.  The  reserves  were  $4,551,076,  and  the  outstanding  loans 
$47,560,000,  while  a  dividend  was  declared  of  8.4  per  cent. 

The  Agricultural  Bank  of  the  Philippines  was  established 
in  1908  on  lines  similar  to  the  Egyptian  institution.  The 
Insular  Government  appropriated  the  sum  of  $500,000  for 
its  capital.  The  Bank  is  managed  by  a  board  of  directors, 
composed  of  the  Secretary  of  Finance  and  Justice,  the  insu- 
lar Treasurer,  and  three  members  appointed  by  the  Governor 
General  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  the  Philippine  Com- 
mission. The  first  mentioned  Secretary  of  Finance  and  Jus- 
tice is  chairman  of  the  board  and  the  insular  Treasurer  is 
manager. 

The  Bank  may  receive  deposits  from  anyone,  but  it  may 
grant  loans  to  farmers  alone,  and  to  them  only  to  lift  prior 
encumbrances  on  agricultural  lands,  to  aid  in  the  purchase, 
cultivation  and  improvement  of  such  lands,  to  purchase  fer- 
tilizers, seeds,  machinery,  implements,  and  animals  to  be 
used  exclusively  in  agriculture,  and  to  pay  the  expenses  of 
planting,  caring  for  and  harvesting  farm  crops  and  prepar- 
ing them  for  the  market.  The  smallest  loan  permitted  is 
$25  and  the  largest  $17,500.  One  half  of  the  capital  of  the 
bank  must  be  set  aside  for  loans  of  not  more  than  $1,000 


LAND   CEEDIT   OUTSIDE   OF  ET7E0PE      193 

First  mortgages,  real  or  personal,  are  always  required  for 
security,  and  no  more  than  60  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the 
mortgaged  property  may  be  loaned.  Loans  are  granted  upon 
resolution  of  the  board  of  directors,  but  no  real-estate  mort- 
gage may  be  accepted  until  the  title  of  the  property  has  been 
passed  on  by  the  Attorney  General. 

This  Philippiae  Agricultural  Bank  now  has  34  agencies  in 
active  operation.  It  has  invested  in  loans  all  its  capital,  be- 
sides a  few  thousand  dollars  of  deposits  received  from  the 
provincial  governments.  By  order  of  the  Governor  General, 
not  to  exceed  20  per  cent  of  the  minimum  which  such  de- 
posits have  reached  during  the  past  six  years  may  be  so  in- 
vested. The  Bank  is  authorized  to  make  20-year  loans  but 
none  actually  granted  runs  over  five  years.  The  maximum 
interest  rate  is  ten  per  cent.  Bonds  or  debentures  may  not 
be  issued. 

The  State  Advances  Act  of  South  Australia  of  1895,  with 
amendments  of  1897  and  1901,  authorized  the  creation  of  a 
state  bank  to  be  managed  by  five  trustees  and  a  general  in- 
spector appointed  by  the  Governor,  with  power  to  issue  mort- 
gage bonds  guaranteed  by  the  state.  Loans  may  be  made  to 
farmers,  cattlemen,  and  other  persons  engaged  in  rural  in- 
dustries, such  as  freezing  meats  and  the  manufacture  of  dairy 
products  and  wines,  for  their  particular  purposes,  and  to 
public  authorities  for  building  bridges,  wharfs,  roads  and 
making  other  permanent  improvements.  The  term  may  be 
from  seven  to  42  years,  and  the  amount  may  be,  for  mort- 
gage loans,  three-fifths  of  the  value  of  the  unimproved  prop- 
erty plus  one-third  of  the  value  of  any  improvement  thereon, 
with  a  maximum  of  $25,000  to  any  one  person.  The  loans 
may  be  made  either  in  cash  or  by  exchanging  the  bonds  of 
the  bank  for  the  mortgage  of  the  borrower.  Eepayment  is 
made  by  half-yearly  annuities  including  an  interest  charge 
which  must  not  exceed  five  per  cent. 

The  Agricultural  Bank  Act  of  Western  Australia  of  1894, 
as  amended  by  1896,  provided  for  a  bank  managed  by  a 
president  appointed  by  the  Governor  for  issuing  government 
five  per  cent  bonds.    Loans  may  be  granted  to  farmers  for 


194  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

making  improvements,  such  as  clearing,  cultivating,  ring- 
barking,  fencing  or  draining  the  land,  digging  wells  and 
constructing  reservoirs,  or  erecting  buildings  for  agricultural 
or  pastoral  use.  The  term  may  be  for  30  years.  The  amount 
must  not  exceed  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  the  improve- 
ments, with  a  maximum  of  $4,000  to  any  one  person.  The 
loan  is  usually  advanced  as  the  improvements  are  made,  and 
is  repaid  by  half-yearly  instalments  of  at  least  one-fiftieth  of 
the  principal,  with  six  per  cent  interest. 

The  Advance  to  Settlers'  Act  of  New  South  Wales  of 
1899  created  a  board  of  three  members  appointed  by  the 
Governor  and  financed  by  the  sale  of  government  stock  bear- 
ing Sy2  per  cent  interest.  Loans  may  be  made  to  purchasers 
of  crown  lands  to  relieve  them  from  financial  diflBculties  due 
to  droughts.  The  term  is  ten  years  and  the  maximum  amount 
$1,000.  If  the  land  is  already  encumbered  the  first  mort- 
gagee must  give  his  consent  before  the  loan  may  be  granted. 

The  Savings  Bank  Act  of  Victoria  of  1890  provided  that 
commissioners  of  the  savings  bank  may,  from  money  obtained 
by  the  sale  of  government  bonds  bearing  4%  per  cent  interest, 
make  loans  to  farmers,  graziers  and  truck  gardeners  or  any 
persons  engaged  in  agricultural,  horticultural  or  pastoral 
pursuits,  to  assist  them  in  paying  ofE  existing  encumbrances  on 
their  lands  and  for  making  improvements.  The  amount  may 
not  exceed  two-thirds  the  value  of  the  land  at  the  time  the 
loan  is  made,  or  be  less  than  $150  or  larger  than  $10,000. 
Special  provisions  exist  for  various  kinds  of  lands.  Eepay- 
ment  is  made  in  63  half-yearly  instalments,  which,  with  4l^ 
per  cent  interest  included,  must  not  exceed  6  per  cent  a  year. 

The  Agricultural  Bank  Act  of  Queensland  of  1901  crea- 
ted a  commission  of  three  trustees  and  a  manager  appointed 
by  the  Governor,  and  authorized  the  raising  of  $1,250,000 
either  by  appropriations  by  the  legislature  or  by  the  sale  of 
debentures  secured  by  the  consols  of  the  state  and  beariag 
not  over  four  per  cent  interest.  Loans  may  be  granted  from 
this  fund  to  homesteaders  of  crown  lands  for  making  numer- 
ous designated  improvements.  The  amount  is  thirteen  shil- 
lings in  the  pound  of  the  estimated  value  of  the  proposed 


LAND    CREDIT   OUTSIDE   OF  EUEOPE      195 

improvement ;  no  person  may  receive  more  than  $4,000.  Ad- 
vances are  made  generally  as  work  on  the  improvement  pro- 
gresses, and  are  paid  back  in  25  years  by  paying  five  per  cent 
interest  for  the  first  five  years,  and  then  by  40  half-yearly 
instalments  of  £4  Os.  6d.  in  the  £100. 

State  aid  is  granted  in  N"ew  Zealand  for  home  coloniza- 
tion and  closer  settlement  on  lands  acquired  from  private 
individuals  as  well  as  on  the  public  domains.  When  private 
property  is  needed  or  desired  for  settlement,  it  may  be  com- 
pulsorily  acquired  if  the  Government  and  owner  cannot  agree 
upon  the  price.  This  state  aid  to  settlers  and  homesteaders 
is  distributed  not  through  banks,  public  or  private,  but 
through  special  boards  or  commissions  which  are  charged 
with  the  duty  of  making  the  loans  out  of  moneys  raised  for 
the  purpose  by  annual  appropriations  or  by  the  issue  of  gov- 
ernment bonds. 

There  are  special  rules  and  regulations  for  the  various 
boards.  Sometimes  the  land  is  sold  to  the  settlers  and  some- 
times it  is  leased.  The  Advances  to  Settlers  OfBce  illustrates 
in  a  general  way  the  methods  adopted  by  the  New  Zealand 
Government  in  carrying  out  its  land-credit  policy.  This  body 
is  a  governmental  department,  supplied  with  a  capital  fund 
of  $30,000,000  by  the  issue  and  sale  of  governmental  bonds 
drawing  not  to  exceed  four  per  cent  interest.  Sums  not  in 
excess  of  $7,500,000  in  any  one  fiscal  year  may  be  raised  in 
this  way  for  the  operations  of  the  oflBce.  If  the  total  amount 
is  not  needed  within  the  year,  the  balance  may  be  added 
to  the  amount  authorized  for  any  subsequent  year.  The  bonds 
are  redeemed  from  a  sinking  fund  created  by  contributions 
of  one  per  cent  of  the  principal  of  loans  made  from  the  pro- 
ceeds of  the  bonds. 

Loans  to  settlers  may  be  for  ten  years  or  under  at  five 
per  cent  per  annum,  or  for  36^^  years  repayable  by  a  semi- 
annual annuity  of  three  per  cent.  The  smallest  loan  on  rural 
property  is  $135,  and  the  largest  $15,000.  For  urban  and 
suburban  properties  the  minimum  is  $1,250,  and  the  maxi- 
mum $10,000.  Prepayments  are  allowed  and  may  be  used 
for  paying  off  entire  annuities,  or  for  paying  off  only  that 


196  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

portion  of  the  annuity  wMcli  represents  the  principal,  or  for 
a  complete  readjustment  of  the  size  and  the  length  of  the 
loan.  First  mortgages  are  always  required  for  security. 
Three-fifths  of  the  value  is  the  very  largest  amount  which 
may  be  advanced  on  any  property. 

In  1882  Mexico  granted  an  exclusive  monopoly  for  20 
years  to  one  land  mortgage  bank  on  condition  that  it  would 
supply  all  the  needs  for  such  an  institution  in  the  Eepublic. 
The  condition  was  not  complied  with  and  the  monopoly  was 
annulled  in  1897,  on  the  passage  of  the  act  on  credit  institu- 
tions in  which  provision  was  made  for  a  plurality  of  banks. 

This  act,  amended  in  1908,  was  largely  the  work  of  Sr. 
Joaquin  D.  Casasus,  chairman  of  the  commission  appointed 
to  formulate  a  bill  to  revise  the  Mexican  banking  laws,  and  his 
report  prepared  for  the  commission  is  a  lumiuous  and  inter- 
esting treatise  on  the  subjects  studied.  As  recommended  by 
Senor  Casasus,  there  are  now  two  kinds  of  financial  institu- 
tions for  assisting  agriculture  in  Mexico,  namely,  land  mort- 
gage banks  and  promotion  banks.  These  banks  obtain  their 
charters  not  from  the  states  but  from  the  federal  executive. 
The  minimum  fixed  for  the  capital  stock  is  one  million  pesos 
($498,000) ,  one-half  of  which  must  be  paid  up  before  begin- 
ning business.  Twenty  per  cent  of  this  sum  must  be  invested 
in  government  bonds.  Ten  per  cent  of  the  net  profits  must 
be  set  aside  each  year  for  creating  a  reserve.  The  articles  of 
agreement  and  by-laws  of  each  bank  must  be  submitted  for 
approval  to  the  Minister  of  Finance,  who  is  charged  with  the 
general  supervision  of  the  banks. 

The  banks  are  supervised  through  inspectors  permanently 
appointed  for  each  bank,  or  through  special  inspectors  ap- 
pointed for  particular  cases,  to  whom  the  Minister  may  give 
such  instructions  as  he  deems  fit.  The  inspectors  must  coun- 
tersign all  debentures,  notes  and  bonds  of  the  banks,  be  pres- 
ent at  drawings  of  these  instruments  for  retirement  and  at 
auction  sales  of  properties  taken  in  foreclosure,  and  see  that 
these  instruments  of  credit  are  not  issued  or  left  in  circula- 
tion in  excess  of  the  legal  limit.  The  periodical  reports  which 
the  banks  are  required  officially  to  make  are  submitted  by 


LAND   CEEDIT   OUTSIDE    OF   ETJEOPB       197 

the  iospectors  to  the  Minister  of  Finance  and  published.  Spe- 
cial proceedings  are  allowed  for  selling  mortgaged  properties 
in  case  of  default  which  cannot  be  interfered  with  by  other 
creditors  of  the  delinquent  debtor.  The  capital  stock,  shares 
and  dividends  of  the  banks  are  exempted  from  taxes,  federal, 
state  or  municipal.  The  debentures,  bonds  and  notes  of  the 
banks  may  be  required  to  be  stamped  but  five  centavos  is  the 
highest  tax.  The  states  or  municipalities  in  which  the  banks 
axe  located  cannot  tax  them  on  their  business.  These  tax 
exemptions  endure,  however,  only  for  the  first  85  years  of  a 
bank's  existence.  The  only  form  of  organization  for  which  the 
laws  provide  is  the  joint-stock  company.  Landschafts  or  asso- 
ciations of  borrowers  are  not  allowed,  so  the  banks  bear  the 
character  of  intermediaries  between  persons  who  have  money 
to  invest  and  rural  or  urban  landowners  who  are  looking  for 
means  to  improve  their  property,  pay  off  its  encumbrances  or 
increase  its  productivity.  The  banks  themselves  directly  nego- 
tiate the  credit  instruments  issued  for  financing  these  trans- 
actions, but  are  authorized  to  realize  the  loans  in  bonds  or 
debentures  instead  of  in  cash  if  they  choose  and  are  able 
to  do  so. 

A  mortgage  bank,  under  the  Mexican  law,  is  one  which 
makes  loans  secured  by  urban  or  rural  lands  and  issues  inter- 
est-bearing bonds  or  debentures  secured  by  such  loans  redeem- 
able under  fixed  conditions  or  at  fixed  times.  The  loans  may 
be  for  either  short  or  long,  term.  The  former  are  those  which 
whether  payable  in  one  or  more  instalments  are  in  all  cases 
less  than  ten  years  in  duration.  The  long-term  loans  are 
those  payable  in  not  less  than  ten  nor  more  than  40  instal- 
ments, whether  quarterly,  semi-annual  or  annual,  comprising 
interest,  a  portion  of  principal  and  the  commission  of  the 
bank.  The  loans  must  be  secured  by  mortgages  on  unencum- 
bered real  estate  located  in  the  state  in  which  the  bank  main- 
tains its  headquarters  and  must  never  exceed  one-half  the 
value  of  such  property,  nor  may  the  annuity  on  the  long- 
term  loans  be  larger  than  the  proceeds  of  the  principal  repre- 
sented by  the  property  estimated  at  stated  rates  as  provided 
by  law.    The  limit  thus  fixed  for  the  loans  must  be  reduced 


198  EUEAL    CREDITS 

to  30  per  cent  of  the  property's  value  when  buildings  consti- 
tute more  than  half  of  its  value,  unless  the  owner  binds 
himself  to  insure  the  buildings  for  the  entire  period  of  the 
loan.  The  value  is  determined  by  experts  appointed  by  the 
banks,  unless  the  Minister  of  Finance  allows  the  banks  to 
operate  on  fiscal  valuations. 

The  aggregate  amount  of  the  mortgage  loans  of  a  bank 
must  never  at  any  one  time  exceed  20  times  its  paid-ia  capital, 
nor  may  loans  to  a  single  person  or  corporation  exceed  one- 
fifth  of  that  capital.  Loans  may  be  paid  in  advance  either  in 
whole  or  in  part.  If  the  mortgaged  property  depreciates 
in  value,  a  bank  may  call  upon  the  borrower  to  give  additional 
security.  Payments  due  mortgage  banks  for  principal  or 
interest  cannot  be  subject  to  attachment,  even  though  applica- 
tion be  made  therefor  in  due  form  before  competent  judicial 
authorities.  In  the  event  of  default  the  banks  have  a  summary 
legal  process  for  foreclosure  and  sale  which  may  not  be  inter- 
fered with  by  third  parties.  A  bank  may  buy  if  there  are  no 
other  bidders  at  the  auction  sale,  but  may  not  hold  real  estate 
over  three  years. 

The  nominal  value  of  the  debentures  of  a  mortgage  bank 
must  never  exceed  the  amount  of  the  mortgage  loans.  The 
interest  rate  is  determined  by  the  bank.  The  denominations 
of  the  debentures  are  100,  500  and  1,000  pesos  ($498).  They 
are  transferable  by  mere  delivery  from  hand  to  hand  or  by 
indorsement,  according  as  they  are  made  payable  to  bearer  or 
are  in  the  name  of  the  holder.  They  may  be  issued  with  or 
without  a  fixed  date  for  redemption;  if  issued  without  a 
fixed  date  they  are  paid  off  by  drawings.  With  permission 
of  the  Minister  of  Finance  premiums  and  prizes  may  be 
allowed  at  the  payment  of  either  interest  or  principal.  The 
drawings  take  place  twice  a  year,  and  at  each  drawing  enough 
debentures  must  be  redeemed  to  keep  the  nominal  value  of 
those  in  circulation  at  a  figure  not  exceeding  the  net  amount 
of  the  outstanding  mortgage  loans.  The  drawings  must  be 
held  in  public  after  publication  in  the  official  newspaper,  and 
must  be  presided  over  by  a  government  inspector.  One  week 
after  the  drawing  the  numeros  of  the  debentures  retired  must 


LAND   CREDIT   OUTSIDE   OF   EUROPE      199 

be  officially  advertised  and  the  date  set  after  which  payment 
shall  be  made.  Debentures  withdrawn  by  drawing  lots  must 
be  canceled.  Those  acquired  by  purchase  or  from  borrowers 
who  use  them  for  payments  on  their  loans  may  be  returned 
to  circulation. 

The  debentures  have  a  lien  upon  the  mortgage  loans  su- 
perior to  that  of  any  other  creditors  of  the  bank.  They  may 
be  issued  in  advance  of  the  loans,  but  any  loan  made  in  money 
which  has  to  be  obtained  by  the  sale  of  debentures  or  bonds 
must  be  on  the  condition  that  its  completion  shall  depend 
upon  the  results  of  such  sale.  This  enables  a  bank  to  finance 
its  loan  operations  without  touching  its  capital  or  other  funds, 
but  the  equilibrium  prescribed  by  statute  between  the  deben- 
tures and  the  loans  must  be  restored  at  the  next  drawing.  In 
addition  to  the  mortgages  each  bank  must  accumulate  a  special 
guaranty  fund  to  assure  prompt  payment  of  the  interest  and 
principal  of  the  debentures.  This  fund  must  always  be  larger 
than  the  aggregate  amoimt  of  the  half-yearly  interest  on  de- 
bentures in  circulation.  Besides  the  tax  exemptions  already 
noted,  the  debentures  have  certain  other  privileges.  They 
have  right  of  property  not  only  to  the  mortgages  taken,  but 
also  to  the  reserves,  guaranty  fund,  and  capital  whether  paid 
up  or  uncalled  for.  Holders  may  bring  summary  action  upon 
refusal  of  the  banks  to  pay  interest  or  principal  when  due  after 
demand  made  therefor  by  a  notary.  The  payment  of  principal 
or  interest  cannot  be  prevented  or  delayed  by  any  judicial 
order,  except  when  the  debentures  have  been  lost  or  stolen. 
The  funds  of  corporations  or  incompetent  persons  may  be 
used  in  purchasing  debentures  in  all  cases  in  which  funds  of 
such  persons  may  be  invested  in  real-estate  mortgages. 

Land  mortgage  banks  may  receive  deposits  only  up  to  twice 
the  amount  of  their  paid-in  capital  and  reserves.  They  must 
always  hold  in  cash  at  least  one-half  of  these  deposits  on  sight 
or  at  three  days'  call.  The  other  half  may  consist  of  sums 
immediately  realizable  or  negotiable  and  of  paper  discounted 
for  not  longer  than  six  months,  the  latter  not  to  exceed  25 
per  cent  of  the  whole  amount  of  the  deposits.  The  banks  may 
make  loans  without  mortgage  for  public  works  or  improve- 


200  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

ments  by  virtue  of  contracts  entered  into  with  the  federal, 
state  or  municipal  governments.  These  may  be  secured  by 
the  securities  issued  against  the  works  or  improvements  in 
question. 

The  Mexican  promotion  banks,  which  are  specially  de- 
signed to  encourage  mining,  agricultural  and  industrial  enter- 
prises, make  preferred  loans  unsecured  by  mortgage,  guarantee 
undertakings,  and  issue  short-time  treasury  bonds  or  certifi- 
cates running  for  a  fixed  time  and  payable  on  specified  dates. 
They  may  make  cash  loans  both  to  farmers  owning  and  op- 
erating their  own  land  and  to  tenants  and  other  persons 
engaged  in  agricultural  pursuits.  Loans  to  landowners  must 
not  exceed  three  years  and  cannot  be  renewed.  They  may  be 
granted  for  the  payment  of  wages,  the  purchase  of  seeds,  raw 
materials,  implements  and  machinery,  administrative  expenses, 
and  the  upkeep  or  preservation  of  property.  The  loan  con- 
tract must  set  forth  the  purpose  of  the  loan  and  be  sworn  to 
before  a'  notary  public.  When  inscribed  in  the  registry  of 
deeds,  it  becomes  a  lien  on  the  property  which  cannot  be  af- 
fected by  any  subsequent  transfer  by  the  owner.  The  size 
of  such  a  loan  must  never  exceed  15  per  cent  of  the  value  of 
the  property.  It  is  the  bank's  duty  to  watch  the  use  of  the 
loan. 

Loans  to  tenants  or  other  persons  engaged  ia  agricultural 
pursuits  on  land  not  owned  by  themselves  must  not  run  for 
a  longer  period  than  two  years.  The  security  must  be  a 
chattel  mortgage  on  farm  products,  crops,  raw  materials,  live 
stock,  implements,  machinery  or  utensils.  When  the  chattel 
mortgage  is  filed,  it  gives  the  bank  a  lien  on  the  personal 
property  described  therein  over  that  of  any  claimant  with  a 
subsequent  title.  The  aggregate  of  the  loans  of  these  two 
classes  which  a  bank  may  make  must  not  exceed  two-thirds 
of  the  amount  of  its  paid-up  capital  and  its  treasury  bonds  in 
circulation. 

Promotion  banks  have  the  same  rights  of  summary  pro- 
ceedings to  enforce  their  claims  enjoyed  by  land  mortgage 
banks,  and  are  subject  to  the  same  rules  governing  loans 
on  collateral  made  by  banks  of  issue.     The  notes  or  other 


LAND    CREDIT   OUTSIDE    OF  EUEOPE      201 

security  which  promotion  banks  may  discount  or  guarantee  to 
facilitate  negotiation  must  not  run  for  longer  than  six  months. 
The  treasury  bonds  which  they  are  authorized  to  issue  must 
be  redeemable  within  periods  which  may  not  be  less  than  three 
months  or  more  than  three  years.  The  amount  of  the  treasury 
bonds  of  a  promotion  bank  in  circulation  must  not  exceed 
at  any  one  time  double  the  paid-up  capital  stock.  Such  a 
bank  is  required  to  keep  in  cash  on  hand  at  least  40  per  cent 
of  the  amount  of  its  deposits  payable  on  demand  or  within  not 
more  than  three  days,  with  the  option,  howcTer,  of  substitut- 
ing for  cash  up  to  one-half  of  this  percentage  securities  which 
are  immediately  convertible.  The  remaining  60  per  cent  of 
deposits  must  be  represented  by  paper  discounted  for  a  period 
of  not  more  than  six  months. 

The  internal  disturbances  which  have  seriously  interfered 
with  all  business  in  Mexico  during  recent  years  have  pre- 
vented the  development  of  banks  under  the  land-credit  law. 
The  present  prices  of  the  debentures  and  bonds  of  the  few 
banks  in  operation  do  not  furnish  a  criterion  for  estimating 
their  intrinsic  value.  The  largest  of  the  banks  is  the  Caja 
Prestamos  para  Obras  de  Irrigacion  y  Fomento  de  la  Agricul- 
tura,  or  Institution  for  the  Encouragement  of  Irrigation 
Works  and  the  Development  of  Agriculture.  The  charter  of 
this  institution  was  granted  by  a  special  act  in  1908.  The 
initial  capital  was  $10,000,000  (Mexican)  divided  into  three 
issues,  of  which  one  belonged  to  the  Government,  one  to  the 
four  banks  which  participated  in  its  formation,  and  one  was 
sold  to  the  public.  The  participating  banks  were  authorized 
to  sell  one-half  of  their  holdings. 

The  chief  object  in  bringing  this  institution  into  existence 
was  to  take  off  the  hands  of  banks  of  issue  a  lot  of  securities 
which  they  had  acquired  in  financing  irrigation  and  land- 
development  projects.  The  Institution  is  empowered  to  grant 
loans  secured  by  mortgage  or  pledge  upon  the  guaranty  of  any 
of  the  four  banks  which  participated  in  its  foundation.  It 
is  authorized  to  issue  debentures  against  these  loans  in  the 
same  way  in  which  a  bank  of  issue  may  issue  notes.  The 
debentures  are  guaranteed  both  as  to  interest  and  principal 


202  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

by  the  Federal  Government,  which  obligates  itself  to  place 
at  the  disposal  of  the  Institution  the  amount  needed  to  meet 
all  payments  when  due.  The  management  of  this  semi- 
public  land-credit  and  land-development  institution  is  lodged 
in  a  board  of  15  directors,  of  whom  three  are  chosen  by  the 
Mexican  Federal  Government. 

The  Argentine  Eepublic  has  three  public  land-credit  in- 
stitutions. The  largest  is  the  Banco  Hipotecario  Naeional 
founded  in  1886.  The  Government  guarantees  the  in- 
terest and  the  principal  of  the  notes  and  bonds  which  this 
bank  is  authorized  to  issue  for  financing  its  operations.  The 
bank  may  grant  building  loans  in  Buenos  Ayres  and  in  cities 
of  more  than  50,000  inhabitants  to  a  total  amount  fixed  for 
each  branch  by  the  board  of  managers.  Ordinary  building 
loans  may  not  exceed  30  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the  mort- 
gaged property;  special  loans  to  owners  of  small  lots  in 
Buenos  Ayres,  up  to  $5,790,  60  per  cent  of  the  mortgaged 
property;  special  loans  for  building  workmen's  dwellings,  60 
per  cent  of  the  mortgaged  property ;  special  loans  for  aflEores- 
tation  and  the  construction  of  industrial  plants  within  five 
kilometers  of  a  port  or  railway  station,  40  per  cent  of  the 
mortgaged  property;  and  loans  on  vineyards  five  years  old,  40 
per  cent  of  the  mortgaged  property.  In  all  these  cases  the 
loans  are  made  not  in  cash  but  in  notes  of  hand  of  the  bank 
given  to  the  borrower  in  exchange  for  his  mortgage. 

Cash  loans  may  be  granted  by  this  Argentine  National 
Land  Bank  on  any  lands  for  sums  not  exceeding  $1,930  or  for 
a  term  not  exceeding  five  years,  repayable  in  lump  or  by 
instalments ;  to  farmers  up  to  80  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the 
mortgaged  property  as  determined  by  the  assessment  for  the 
land  tax,  to  a  maximum  of  $2,895;  and  for  supplying  dwell- 
ings with  water,  between  the  limits  of  $482.50  and  $1,447.50. 

The  bank  must  not  have  more  than  $386,000,000  (Mexi- 
can) of  its  notes  of  hand  in  circulation  at  any  one  time.  In 
addition,  however,  it  may,  with  the  consent  of  the  Govern- 
ment, issue  $28,350,000  of  bonds  to  be  used  exclusively  in 
making  mortgage  loans.  The  reserves  of  the  bank  must  be 
increased  each  year  by  30  per  cent  of  the  annual  profits.    This 


LAND    CEEDIT   OUTSIDE    OF   EUROPE      203 

fund  must  be  invested  in  government  securities.  The  rest 
of  the  profits  may  be  used  in  making  cash  loans. 

Land  credit  was  organized  in  Chile  while  the  Indian  and 
buffalo  in  western  United  States  could  roam  from  the  Gulf  of 
Mexico  to  the  Canadian  border  without  crossing  a  railroad 
track  or  seeing  the  face  of  a  white  settler.  Loans  of  33  years, 
repayable  by  annuities,  were  being  granted  m  Chile  when  the 
farmers  of  Kansas  were  losing  their  homesteads  by  the  fore- 
closure of  three-  and  five-year  mortgages.  Chilean  mortgage 
bonds  or  debentures  are  officially  listed  on  the  Paris  Bourse 
and  have  been  made  legal  investments  by  the  French  Ministry 
of  Finance  for  all  purposes  for  which  even  government  bonds 
may  be  used.  They  are  bought  also  by  English  bankers  and 
find  a  ready  market  in  other  parts  of  the  European  Conti- 
nent where  offers  of  American  mortgage  bonds  would  be  re- 
fused. 

The  Chilean  land-credit  law  was  enacted  in  1855,  three 
years  after  that  of  France,  and  it  has  proved  so  satisfactory 
that  very  few  amendments  have  been  made.  The  law  is  a 
general  one,  allowing  any  persons  who  comply  with  its  terms 
to  form  a  company.  A  number  of  companies  have  been 
formed  thereunder  and  are  doing  a  good  business.  Neverthe- 
less they  operate  at  a  disadvantage,  because  of  the  fact  that 
the  Chilean,  like  the  French,  Government  organized  a  state 
bank  under  the  general  law,  and  although  it  has  not  given 
this  institution  a  monopoly  it  has  invested  it  with  such  privi- 
leges that  no  others  can  compete  with  it  successfully.  It 
holds  two-thirds  of  the  mortgages  taken  by  bond-issuing  land 
banks  in  Chile,  and  it  is  able  to  hold  so  many  more  than  its 
competitors  that  it  absolutely  dictates  the  rate  of  interest. 

This  institution  is  called  the  Caja  de  Credito  Hipo- 
tecario,  or  Chilean  State  Land  Mortgage  Bank.  It  has 
no  capital  stock  or  shareholders.  It  is  owned  and  managed 
by  the  Government,  and  the  net  profits  are  used  for  the 
benefit  of  borrowers  or  for  creating  or  supporting  savings 
banks.  The  President  of  the  Republic  appoints  the  managing 
director  of  the  bank  on  his  own  motion,  its  secretary  upon 
nomination  of  the  managing  director,   and  the  treasurer. 


204  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

cashier  and  inspector  upon  nomination  of  the  board  of  direc- 
tors. The  board  is  composed  of  these  officials,  two  directors 
elected  by  the  Senate  and  two  elected  by  the  House  of  Eep- 
resentatives.  One  of  each  of  these  two  pairs  must  be  chosen 
from  among  the  heaviest  borrowers  of  the  bank  who  are  land- 
owners, but  the  positions  are  honorary  and  draw  no  salary. 
The  powers  and  duties  of  the  board  are  determined,  within 
the  scope  laid  down  in  the  law,  by  the  President  of  the  Ee- 
public  with  the  consent  of  the  Council  of  State.  Another 
feature  peculiar  to  this  bank  is  that  the  appraisal  of  prop- 
erties offered  for  mortgage  is  made  by  a  commission  of  experts 
appointed  by  the  board  upon  nomination  of  the  borrowers. 

The  Caja  de  Credito  Hipotecario  lends  on  the  security  of 
unencumbered  real  estate  situated  in  the  Eepublic  up  to  a 
maximum  of  one-half  its  value  for  ordinary  borrowers,  and 
of  three-fourths  its  value  for  the  purchase  or  construction  of 
cheap  dwellings;  and  without  mortgage  to  a  large  irrigation 
company,  created  by  a  special  act  of  1908,  up  to  a  certain 
designated  portion  of  the  value  of  its  assets  and  credit  stand- 
ing. The  minimum  loan  is  500  pesos  ($104)  on  property 
worth  at  least  2,000  pesos  ($416),  but  the  smallest  loan 
actually  granted  is  $624  on  property  worth  $2,080.  The 
loans  are  not  made  in  cash.  They  are  effected  by  exchanging 
the  bonds  of  the  Bank  for  the  note  and  mortgage  of  the 
borrower,  but  as  the  Bank  undertakes  to  sell  the  bonds  with- 
out commission  for  the  borrower,  the  loan  becomes  a  cash 
transaction  as  a  matter  of  fact. 

These  bonds  are  issued  in  series,  either  in  the  name  of 
the  holder  or  payable  to  bearer,  in  denominations  of  about 
$20,  $50,  $100  and  $200.  The  issues  in  circulation  include 
eight  per  cents  redeemable  within  28  years,  seven  per  cents 
redeemable  within  30%  years,  six  per  cents  redeemable  within 
33  years,  and  five  per  cents  redeemable  within  25%  years, 
to  mention  only  those  with  the  longest  periods.  The  appli- 
cant who  is  granted  a  loan  obligates  himself  to  pay  the  in- 
terest on  the  bonds  in  which  he  chooses  to  have  it  made, 
together  with  the  necessary  instalments  to  effect  the  redemp- 
tion of  the  bonds  at  their  maturity  and  one-fourth  of  one 


LAND    CEEDIT   OUTSIDE   OF   EUEOPE      205 

per  cent  in  addition  for  expenses  and  reserve.  These  sums 
are  combined  to  form  an  annuity,  one-half  of  which  must  be 
paid  every  six  months.  In  this  way  the  borrower  amortizes 
his  debt  to  the  Bank  at  and  by  the  time  the  Bank  is  called 
upon  to  pay  the  interest  and  the  principal  of  its  own  bonds 
to  the  holders.  If  the  borrower  should  default  his  annuity, 
the  Bank,  by  a  special  summary  procedure  may,  after  30  days' 
notice,  take  possession  of  the  mortgaged  property  and  sell  it 
at  public  auction.  Besides  this  judicial  privilege  the  bonds 
of  the  Bank  have  been  made  legal  investments  for  all  persons 
and  purposes  and  have  been  purchased  in  large  amounts  by 
the  Chilean  Government,  not  only  because  of  their  intrinsic 
soundness  but  in  order  to  give  them  a  popular  currency. 
The  bonds  are  guaranteed  by  the  state,  which  has  for  its 
own  protection  the  mortgages  taken  from  borrowers  and  the 
reserve.  The  reserve  fund  at  present,  however,  is  small, 
amounting  to  only  3.335  per  cent  of  the  face  value  of  the 
total  bonds  in  circulation.  The  state  has  suffered  severe 
losses  on  several  occasions  on  account  of  this  guaranty. 

The  Banco  Hipotecario  del  Uruguay,  formerly  a  private 
company,  was  converted  into  a  public  institution  about  two 
years  ago.  It  is  authorized  to' grant  loans  up  to  60  per  cent 
of  the  value  of  the  land.  Its  bonds  are  actively  dealt  in  on 
the  stock  exchanges  of  Uruguay,  and  find  a  market  in  some 
European  countries.  The  bonds  are  secured  by  the  first 
mortgages  taken  for  the  loans,  and  are  guaranteed  both  as 
to  principal  and  interest  by  the  Uruguayan  Government. 

In  1913  Costa  Eica  founded  a  state 'land  mortgage  bank 
similar  to  that  of  Chile.  A  new  feature  was  added  to  the 
law,  however,  in  order  to  force  capitalists  to  buy  the  bonds  of 
the  bank.  The  deposits  of  all  individuals  and  corporations 
in  commercial  and  savings  banks  are  taxed  two  per  cent 
whether  they  are  drawing  interest  or  not.  At  the  same 
time  the  bonds  of  the  state  mortgage  bank  were  exempted 
from  taxation  and  made  lawful  investments  for  the  funds  of 
guardians  and  trustees  and  acceptable  by  the  state  in  all 
cases  ia  which  the  law  requires  the  deposit  of  cash  or  security 
to  assure  the  faithful  performance  of  public  duties. 


206  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

In  1911  the  Territorial  Bank  of  Cuba,  a  private  joint- 
stock  company  with  a  capital  of  $5,000,000  with  right  to 
indefinite  increase  thereof,  was  given  an  exclusive  monopoly 
for  60  years  to  issue  bonds  or  other  instruments  of  credit 
on  the  basis  of  reducible  short-  or  long-term  loans  secured  by 
mortgage  on  real  estate  situated  in  the  Eepublic.  The  maxi- 
mum interest  on  loans  is  fixed  at  seven  per  cent,  and  the 
bank  is  required  to  devote  a  part  of  its  capital  to  the  needs 
of  agriculture. 

It  remains  to  complete  the  survey  of  land-credit  systems 
only  to  describe  one  of  the  latest  of  European  development, 
the  use  of  life-insurance  policies  as  security  for  loans.  Dur- 
ing the  first  epoch  of  its  history  and  even  down  to  the  mid- 
dle of  the  past  century,  the  institutions  which  handled  life 
insurance  were  not  aU  especially  and  exclusively  devoted  to 
that  purpose,  as  is  generally  the  case  today.  Banks  and 
various  moneyed  concerns  frequently  carried  on  insurance 
in  connection  with  their  other  business.  To  mention  a  few 
out  of  many  instances,  the  Discount  and  Mortgage  Bank  of 
Bavaria,  founded  in  1835  at  Mimich,  had  life  insurance  as 
one  of  its  objects.  The  Eent-Charge  Bank,  founded  shortly 
afterwards  iu  the  Grand  Duchy  of  Hesse-Darmstadt,  issued 
and  sold  tontines  and  life  policies.  Several  old  trust  com- 
panies in  New  York  and  Philadelphia  are  operating  under 
charters  with  similar  provisions,  although  they  have  not  made 
use  of  them  for  many  years. 

However,  ftnance  and  insurance  are  intimately  aUied,  and 
the  idea  of  protecting  the  claims  of  a  creditor  by  insuring 
in  his  favor  the  life  of  the  debtor  was  put  in  practice  at  an 
early  date  and  is  now  gradually  spreading.  Another  applica- 
tion of  insurance  quite  common  in  European  cities  is  the 
taking  out  of  a  policy  by  the  purchaser  of  a  dwelling  to  cover 
any  balance  of  the  price  unpaid  at  his  death,  so  as  to  save 
his  family  from  the  possibility  of  being  deprived  of  the 
property  by  the  mortgagee.  This  latter  idea  more  recently 
has  been  adopted  for  country  districts,  and  in  Germany, 
Belgium,  France  and  Hungary  plans  have  been  devised  and 
actually  carried  out  for  completely  replacing  mortgages  by 


LAND   CEEDIT   OUTSIDE   OF  EUROPE      207 

life-insurance  policies  as  security  for  long-term  mortgage 
loans. 

The  East  Prussian  Landschaft  was  the  first  institution 
to  take  such  a  step  ia  Germany.  In  1910  it  created  an  in- 
surance company  and  endowed  it  with  $240,000  in  3.5  per 
cent  debentures.  Policies  may  be  issued  on  the  lives  of  mem- 
bers of  the  landschaft  and  of  all  other  residents  of  the  prov- 
ince. The  landschaft  uses  the  annual  instalments  which  its 
borrowing  members  pay  on  the  principal  of  their  loans  as 
premiums  on  the  policies  obtained  from  the  company,  and 
in  this  way  these  members  are  insured  up  to  the  full  amount 
of  their  loans  without  being  required  to  pay  anything  in  addi- 
tion to  their  annuities.  Other  policy-holders  also  get  cheap 
insurance,  because  the  company  is  purely  altruistic,  distrib- 
utes no  dividends,  large  salaries  or  commissions,  and  so  con- 
ducts its  business  at  less  cost  than  other  insurance  com- 
panies. Public  insurance  companies  of  a  similar  nature  have 
been  founded  in  West  Prussia,  Pomerania,  Posen,  and  Silesia, 
with  the  assistance  of  the  landschafts  in  some  cases,  with, 
the  object  of  dismortgaging  the  land,  popularizing  insurance 
among  farmers,  and  preventing  the  large  joint-stock  com- 
panies from  drawing  money  away  from  the  agricultural 
regions. 

In  1910  also  France  by  law  authorized  the  cooperative 
credit  societies  belonging  to  the  system  called  the  Credit 
Agricole  to  accept  the  policies  of  the  National  Assurance 
Society  in  place  of  mortgages  as  security  for  loans  made  for 
acquiring  or  improving  small  homesteads.  In  1911  Himgary 
followed  by  allowing  the  Hungarian  Central  Society  for 
Cooperative  Credit  to  do  the  same  with  members  of  aflBliated 
cooperative  credit  societies,  the  company  with  which  it  was 
permitted  to  do  business  being  the  First  General  Hungarian 
Life  Insurance  Society.  In  both  these  countries  the  coop- 
erative society  may  advance  to  the  applicant  or  member  a 
sum  of  money  sufficient  for  him  to  purchase  by  one  single 
premium  a  term  policy  for  the  length  of  the  loan,  to  protect 
the  society  from  loss  of  whatever  amount  remains  unpaid 
should  he  die  within  that  time.    This  premium  is  added  tO' 


508  EFEAL   CREDITS 

-the  loan,  and  the  policy  is  made  out  in  favor  of  the  society 
or  assigned  to  it  and  used  as  security  for  its  claims  in  place 
•of  a  mortgage.  In  the  event  of  death  the  cooperative  credit 
society  receives  the  proceeds  of  the  policy  from  the  insurance 
•company,  applies  them  towards  settling  all  its  claims  against 
-the  decedent,  and  turns  the  property  over  to  his  heirs  free 
and  clear  of  all  encumbrances. 

This  arrangement  is  available  of  course  only  for  the 
sound  and  healthy,  nor  is  it  of  much  service  to  them  unless 
-they  be  under  middle  age  and  can  obtain  money  at  very  low- 
interest  rates,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  the  French  and  Hun- 
garian insurance  companies  give  a  preferential  rate  of  in- 
surance to  this  class  of  business.  This  reduction  is  possible 
because  the  risk  decreases  as  time  progresses,  since  the  loan 
is  amortizable  and  the  unpaid  portion  for  which  the  insur- 
ance company  is  liable  grows  smaller  year  by  year  by  the 
annuities  or  instalments  on  the  principal  which  the  bor- 
rower is  obligated  to  pay  every  six  months.  In  France,  where 
-the  cooperative  societies  make  loans  at  2.5  per  cent  with 
money  supplied  by  the  Government,  the  annuity  required 
for  extinguishing  a  loan  without  insurance  in  15  years  is 
$80.76  per  $1,000.  For  such  a  loan  with  insurance  premium 
incorporated  for  a  man  between  30  and  31  years  old,  the 
annuity  is  $88.75,  a  difference  of  only  $7.99  per  $1,000. 


CHAPTEE    XIX 

THE  PUINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CREDIT  AND  THEIR 
APPLICATION 

Distinguishing  Feature  of  land-credit  Institutions  the  Power  tO' 
Issue  Debentures. — These  Not  Possible  to  Usual  Money  Lenders. 
— Private  Institutions  and  Landschafts. — Loans  Made  to  Spe- 
cial Classes. — ^Regulations  and  Powers. — Organizations  of  Euro- 
pean Countries  Compared. — Security  of  Loans. — TJnrecallable 
Long-term  Debenture  Necessary  for  Long-term  Credit. — Situa- 
tion in  United  States  and  Europe. — Comparison  of  Silesian 
Landschaft  and  Possible  Organization  in  Kansas. — Wisconsin 
Land  Mortgage  Associations  Act. — ^Land  Bank  of  the  State  of 
New  York. — ^Rural  Business  of  Savings  and  Loan  Associations. 
— Ohio — CoUeetive  Saving  Different  from  Cooperative  Credit. — 
Desirability  of  American  Landschafts. 

The  foregoing  chapters  show  the  various  forms  which 
land  credit  has  assumed  in  the  European  and  the  few  other 
countries  in  which  it  has  been  organized.  They  do  not 
attempt  to  give,  of  course,  a  full  account  of  all  institutions 
actually  existing.  This  would  have  involved  useless  repetition, 
since  many  of  them  are  exactly  alike.  Nor  has  more  than 
passing  notice  been  directed  hitherto  towards  individual 
money  lenders,  companies  and  banks  which  take  mortgages  of 
real  estate  simply  by  way  of  investment  for  otherwise  unpro- 
ductive funds,  because  there  is  nothing  of  especial  interest  in 
their  methods  except  in  Germany,  Great  Britain  and  Ireland. 

In  Germany  a  very  heavy  business  in  second  mortgages 
at  high  interest  rates  is  done  by  individual  money  lenders, 
because  of  the  fact  that  a  borrower  is  unable  to  realize  on 
the  full  credit  value  of  his  property  in  a  loan  from  the  land- 
credit  institutions  on  account  of  their  exceedingly  conserva- 
tive appraisals  and  the  wide  margin  demanded  for  security. 

209 


210  EFEAL   CEEDITS 

In  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  there  are  no  private  bond  and 
mortgage  institutions,  except  for  land  improvement  projects. 
Some  attribute  their  absence  to  defective  registration  laws, 
but  it  is  perhaps  due  to  the  firmly  established  custom  of  ac- 
cording land  credit  on  recallable  loans  and  to  the  very  satis- 
factory results  of  this  practice  which  arise  from  local  condi- 
tions. / 

As  a  rule  in  the  British  Isles  the  principal  of  a  recall- 
able loan  may  be  recovered  within  a  few  weeks  at  the  will  of 
the  lender,  who  may  exercise  this  right  to  raise  the  interest 
rate  whenever  money  is  dear.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  however, 
this  is  rarely  done,  or  if  it  is  done  the  rate  written  in  the 
mortgage  is  quickly  restored,  because  the  English  market, 
regulated  by  the  great  mart  of  London,  is  generally  steady. 
As  a  consequence,  interest  rates  in  the  British  Isles  compare 
favorably  with  those  in  countries  where  land  credit  is  highly 
organized,  and  there  is  thus  no  pressing  need  of  substituting 
special  institutions  for  the  present  English  system  of  private 
money  lenders,  individual  or  incorporated. 

With  the  exceptions  noted,  nothing  material  to  the  sub- 
ject has  been  omitted  from  these  chapters,  while  every  orig- 
inal type  of  land-credit  institution  or  system  and  important 
variant  has  been  described  with  sufBcient  clearness,  it  is 
hoped,  to  furnish  a  basis  for  a  brief  analysis  and  explana- 
tion of  their  underlying  principles.  The  distinguishing 
feature  of  land-credit  institutions,  it  will  be  recalled,  is 
the  power  to  issue  interest-bearing  mortgage  bonds  or  deben- 
tures. European  land-credit  laws  relate  only  to  institutions 
having  or  seeking  this  power,  and  institutions  are  hardly 
considered  to  have  a  land-credit  character  in  Europe  until 
they  are  so  empowered.  Furthermore,  the  granting  of  long- 
term  loans,  that  is,  for  periods  of  10  to  75  years  or  more, 
is  so  generally  their  practice,  that  it  may  be  said  that  this 
is  the  chief  if  not  the  only  reason  for  bringing  them  into 
existence.  There  are  notable  exceptions  in  this  regard,  as, 
for  instance,  the  joint-stock  land  mortgage  banks  of  Germany. 
These  banks,  however,  operate  in  a  large  measure  with  their 
own  capital  stocks  and  demand  urban  properties  as  security 


PRINCIPLES   OP  LAND  CEEDIT  211 

for  practically  all  their  loans.  There  are  no  exceptions  in 
the  case  of  institutions  dealing  exclusively  or  to  a  large 
extent  with  rural  properties. 

A  farmer  who  makes  his  living  solely  by  agriculture  can- 
not pay  the  purchase  price  of  land  or  the  cost-  of  permanent 
improvements  except  as  he*  recovers  their  value  from  the  net 
gains  of  his  industry,  the  surplus  after  he  has  paid  his  taxes, 
interest,  and  cost  of  upkeep  and  repair  of  his  property  and 
the  support  of  himself  and  family.  These  gains  come  as 
much  from  manual  labor  as  from  the  beneficence  of  nature. 
Like  the  proceeds  from  all  manual  labor,  they  are  slow  in 
accumulating,  and  unless  artificial  or  outside  means  are  em- 
ployed, they  diminish  as  the  years  advance  and  the  fertility 
of  his  land  is  exhausted.  He  is  his  own  hired  hand,  worked 
the  harder  because  he  is  his  own  employer,  giving  to  others 
the  larger  portion  of  the  fruits  of  his  toil  until  he  owns  his 
farm  free  and  clear  of  aU  encumbrance.  After  that,  he  be- 
comes a  capitalist,  it  is  true,  but  stiU  a  laborer,  a  capitalist- 
laborer,  the  productivity  and  increase  of  whose  capital  depend 
constantly  upon  his  own  personal  labor  and  supervision.  His 
only  alternative  is  the  temporary  and  uncertain  tenure  of  a 
rent-paying  tenant. 

With  the  annual  yields  of  capital  thus  limited  by  the 
personal  supervision  and  labor  actually  applied,  to  it,  a 
farmer  should  not  expect  to  be  supplied  with  money  for  lift- 
ing old  debts  or  acquiriag  new  property  by  individual  money 
lenders,  savings  banks,  commercial  banks  or  any  concerns 
that  require  a  reasonably  quick  turnover  of  their  funds.  The 
maximum  time  allowed  for  paying  off  loans  for  such  pur- 
poses is  30  years  in  Finland,  33  years  in  Chile,  36^/^  years  in 
New  Zealand,  42  years  in  Australia,  50  years  in  Italy  and 
Japan,  54^^  years  in  Austria,  55%  years  in  Russia,  56% 
years  in  Germany  and  Sweden,  57  years  in  Switzerland,  60 
years  in  Denmark,  63  years  in  Hungary,  68%  years  in  Ire- 
land, and  75  years  in  Prance.  And  the  annual  dues,  includ- 
ing interest,  cost  of  business,  and  the  fraction  of  the  prin- 
cipal required  of  the  borrower  for  amortizing  the  debt,  form 
an  annuity  of  only  3%  to  seven  per  cent  of  the  principal  of 


313  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  loan.  In  other  words,  the  farmer  in  the  countries  named 
is  given  at  least  one  generation  and  in  some  cases  more 
than  two  generations  for  paying  back  a  loan,  as  against  three 
to  five  years  in  the  United  States,  while  the  annuity  is  smaller 
on  the  average  than  the  interest  rate  alone  ia  the  southern 
and  western  states.  This  annuity  is  always  so  fijxed  as  to 
leave  the  farmer  enough  of  his  revenues  to  live  on  and  pay 
ordinary  expenses,  and  thus  never  being  called  upon  to  pay 
in  lump  at  a  time  when  it  might  be  difiScult  or  disadvan- 
tageous for  him  to  do  so,  he  is  able  gradually  to  relieve  him- 
self from  debt  by  the  yearly  returns  from  the  soil. 

These  long-term  reducible  mortgage  loans  are  never 
granted  by  individuals  or  ordinary  money  lenders.  They  are 
granted  only  by  the  land-credit  institutions  from  funds  prac- 
tically all  drawn  from  the  investing  public  through  the  issue 
of  mortgage-bonds  or  debentures.  These  institutions  are 
either  public  or  private,  though  a  more  exact  classification 
would  include  a  separate  heading  for  such  as  are  semii-public. 
The  pervading  presence  of  the  state  in  Europe  at  the  initia- 
tory stage  of  many  of  the  old  institutions,  however,  often 
makes  it  difficult  to  distinguish  between  the  semi-public  and 
the  one  or  the  other  of  the  main  classes.  The  public  insti- 
tutions, owned  and  operated  by  the  state,  are  usually  mere 
governmental  bureaus  without  share  capital,  which  obtain 
funds  for  granting  loans  either  by  appropriations  or  by  the 
issue  of  debentures  guaranteed  by  the  state.  The  profits, 
if  any,  are  used  for  extending  business,  set  aside  for  meeting 
losses,  or  devoted  to  some  public  purpose. 

The  private  land-credit  institutions  are  either  associations 
of  borrowers  or  joint-stock  companies.  The  semi-public  land- 
credit  institutions,  or  those  in  which  the  state  is  a  part 
owner,  participates  in  the  control  or  management,  or  as- 
sumes a  responsibility  of  some  sort,  may  be  similarly  classi- 
fied. The  joint-stock  companies  aim  to  make  profit  and, 
unless  they  are  semi-public,  strive  to  declare  as  large  divi- 
dends as  possible.  The  proportion  of  the  surplus  which  may 
be  annually  distributed  in  dividends  is  never  limited,  pro- 
vided the  institution  is  not  purely  eleemosynary,  but  it  may 


PEINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT  213 

be  subject,  however,  to  a  regulation,  such  as  that  all  profits 
over  a  five  per  cent  dividend  on  the  capital  stock  each  year 
shall  be  written  to  the  reserve  until  this  fund  equals  one- 
half  of  the  capital  stock. 

The  associations  of  borrowers,  or  landschafts,  have  no 
capital  stock  or  lucrative  object,  and  if  they  happen  to  ac- 
cumulate a  surplus  from  earnings  or  savings,  it  belongs  to 
the  members  and  is  distributed  in  rebates  of  principal  and 
interest  in  proportion  to  the  amounts  paid  up  on  their 
loans.  The  old  German  landschaft  is  the  original  type  of 
land-credit  institution.  Modified  forms  of  it  exist  in  Sweden, 
Denmark,  Eussia,  Austria-Hungary,  Eoumania,  Switzerland, 
Italy  and  Prance.  Except  in  Denmark,  the  landschafts  are 
distinctly  rural,  being  composed  almost  entirely  of  owners 
of  farm  lands  and  confining  their  busiaess  to  granting  long- 
term  loans  on  such  lands  of  their  members. 

The  plans  of  administration  of  the  European  land-credit 
institutions  are  similar  in  the  one  respect  that  they  are  all 
based  on  the  general  idea  of  vesting  the  control  of  the  insti- 
tution, the  actual  management  of  its  business,  and  the  in- 
spection and  audit  of  its  affairs  in  three  separate  and  distinct 
bodies  of  officials,  the  last  of  which  is  absolutely  independent 
of  the  others.  The  first  body  is  the  board  of  directors  or 
executive  council,  which  includes  the  president,  elected  in 
the  private  institutions  by  the  shareholders,  and  in  the  land- 
schafts by  representatives  of  the  members  with  approval  of 
the  Government.  The  second  body  is  composed  of  the  presi- 
dent or  managing  director  and  vice-presidents  charged  with 
such  duties  as  he  or  the  directors  assign  to  them.  For  the 
third  body  there  is  sometimes  a  standing  committee  of  audi- 
tors elected  by  the  shareholders  or  appointed  by  the  Govern- 
ment. In  Germany  the  Government  appoints  a  fiduciary 
agent  for  each  land  mortgage  bank,  who  holds  in  trust  all 
mortgages  used  as  security  for  bonds  and  countersigns  all 
bonds  issued.  But  whatever  the  method  of  selection,  tbe  sup- 
ervisory authority  may  sit  at  all  meetings  of  the  officials  and 
shareholders,  may  inspect  all  books,  cash  and  accounts,  and 
may  put  a  stop,  either  by  direct  action  or  by  appeal  to  the 


214  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

Govermnent,  to  any  transaction  of  which  he  disapproves. 
These  supervisors,  inspectors,  censors  or  auditors,  although 
they  may  be  paid  by  the  institution,  are  in  no  wise  beholden 
to  it.  Their  chief  functions  are  to  stand  between  the  institu- 
tion and  the  bondholders,  to  protect  the  interests  of  the  lat- 
ter, and  to  prevent  violations  and  transgressions  of  the  laws. 
They  and  the  responsible  head  of  the  institution — ^the  presi- 
dent in  some  countries,  the  board  of  directors  in  others — 
are  amenable  to  the  Government  for  the  proper  conduct 
of  the  business  and  afEairs  of  the  institution.  The  Minister 
of  Agriculture  or  the  Minister  of  Finance,  acting  directly 
or  through  a  commissioner  or  bureau,  is  designated  as  tho 
general  supervising  authority,  and  periodical  reports  must 
be  filed  with  him  showing  the  interest  rates  and  amounts  of 
loans  made,  repaid  and  outstanding,  the  amount  of  deben- 
tures issued  and  in  circulation,  and  their  interest  rates  and 
market  quotations. 

The  business  of  the  European  private  land-credit  com- 
panies or  banks  usually  embraces,  besides  mortgage  loans  to 
individuals,  loans  without  mortgages  to  railroads,  public-util- 
ity corporations,  municipalities,  public  corporations  and  co- 
operative societies.  Indeed  the  greater  portion  of  their  busi- 
ness consists  of  loans  to  incorporated  and  associational  bor- 
rowers and  large  landowners.  Loans  for  small  sums  con- 
stitute a  meager  proportion  and  the  amount  of  long-term, 
reducible  or  amortizable  loans  is  negligible.  There  are  two 
reasons  why  the  private  land-credit  companies  or  banks  of 
Europe  do  not  handle  many  small  or  long-term  reducible  farm 
mortgages.  The  first  is,  that  they  find  it  more  easy  and 
profitable  to  make  loans  on  urban  properties  or  to  the  various 
corporations  and  municipalities  which  the  laws  permit  them 
to  finance.  The  second  reason  is  that  few  of  them  have  the 
necessary  standing  and  confidence  of  the  public  to  enable 
them  to  issue  and  negotiate  unrecallable  long-term  deben- 
tures. An  investor  will  not  buy  a  bond  which  has  no  set 
time  for  redemption  or  the  return  of  the  principal  unless 
the  issuing  institution  is  so  large  and  solid  that  there  is  no 
question  of  its  endurance  and  solvency.     So,  failing  in  at- 


PEINCIPLES   OP   LAND   CEEDIT  215 

traeting  money  for  long  term  from  the  inyesting  public,  the 
European  private  land-credit  companies  or  banks  are  not  in 
a  position  to  grant  long-term  loans  to  any  great  extent. 

The  European  public  land-credit  institutions  make  loans 
only  for  specific  purposes  or  to  special  classes  of  persons. 
Hence,  unlike  the  private  institutions,  they  require  that  the 
money  obtained  on  a  loan  shall  be  used  for  the  particular 
object  for  -vrhich  it  was  requested  and  granted.  All  of  them 
"were  organized  and  still  are  operated  either  for  financing  land 
reclamation  and  improvement  projects,  or  else  for  carrying 
out  the  policy  of  the  Government  in  respect  to  the  erection 
of  dweUiug  houses  for  workmen  or  the  creation  of  small 
holdings  for  poor  farmers.  The  first  class  of  public  institu- 
tions may  extend  financial  aid  to  rich  or  well-to-do  farmers. 
They  grant  credit  not  only  on  the  actual  present  value  but 
also  on  the  estimated  value  of  the  land  as  reclaimed  or  im- 
proved. This  means  that  the  security  is  in  part  personal  or 
speculative,  and  thus  they  do  not  aU  come  within  the  strict 
definition  of  a  land-credit  institution.  The  second  class  of 
public  land-credit  institutions  never  assist  farmers  or  persons 
who  are  able  to  take  care  of  themselves.  Their  sole  object 
is  to  help  the  poor  whose  condition  is  so  abject  as  to  preclude 
them  from  credit  from  any  other  source. 

The  weU-to-do  European  farmer  is  yet  too  proud  to  seek 
free  or  cheap  money  from  the  state  to  enable  him  to  acquire 
or  improve  a  farm.  There  are,  however,  conspicuous  excep- 
tions in  Eussia,  where  the  tenure  of  land  is  stUl  undergoing 
readjustment  as  a  result  of  the  abolition  of  the  feudal  sys- 
tem in  1861,  and  in  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  where  the 
nationalization  of  all  land  is  making  headway  through  the 
socialistic  tendencies  of  the  Government.  Much  of  the  land- 
credit  legislation  of  many  European  nations  was  enacted  with 
the  object  of  enabling  poor  and  dependent  persons  to  acquire 
dweUrag  houses  or  small  holdings.  In  fact,  only  in  Germany, 
Prance,  Sweden,  Denmark,  Eussia,  Switzerland,  Austria- 
Hungary  and  Italy  are  there  mortgage-bond  or  debenture- 
issuing  institutions  which  do  any  considerable  business  with 
the  owners  of  large  or  medium-sized  estates,  while  in  these 


216  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

coTintries  that  part  of  the  business  which  consists  of  long- 
term  loans  is  handled  almost  exclusively  by  landsehafts  or 
semi-public  land-credit  institutions.  Private  institutions  seem 
to  be  unable  to  grant  loans  for  a  longer  term  than  five  or  ten 
years  at  most. 

The  rules  and  regulations  which  govern  the  operations 
of  these  institutions  are  very  strict.  The  size  of  an  individual 
loan  is  rarely  over  two-thirds  the  value  of  the  mortgaged 
property,  carefully  calculated  by  arbitrary  formula.  Usually 
it  is  one-half  the  value,  and  only  properties  yielding  or  capa- 
ble of  yielding  a  steady  and  permanent  revenue  may  be  used 
for  security,  the  general  rule  being  that  the  revenue  must 
equal  at  least  the  annuity  which  the  borrower  obligates  him- 
self to  pay. 

The  loans  are  secured  by  first  mortgages  and  are  repay- 
able by  annuities.  The  institutions  have  the  advantage  of 
special  summary  legal  processes  in  order  to  protect  their 
rights  and  assure  prompt  and  regular  payments.  These  relate 
to  the  proving  of  the  title  of  the  property  offered  to  be  mort- 
gaged and  to  the  recovery  of  defaulted  dues.  The  processes 
for  proving  title  are  similar  to  the  Torrens  system,  speedily 
settle  questions  affecting  the  title  of  the  land,  and  enable  the 
owners  to  obtain  loans  without  delay.  In  substance  this 
process  consists  simply  in  publishing  a  notice  in  the  official 
newspaper  of  the  fact  that  a  mortgage  is  about  to  be  placed 
upon  the  property  described,  and  warning  aU  persons  who 
claim  an  interest  therein  to  present  their  claims  for  adjudi- 
cation within  a  few  days  or  weeks.  If  such  claims  are  not 
presented  within  the  time  allowed  or  if  they  are  thrown  out 
of  court,  the  institution  may  safely  grant  the  loan  because 
no  person  with  a  hidden  or  prior  claim  can  attack  its  rights 
under  the  mortgage. 

The  process  allowed  for  the  collection  of  defaulted  dues 
from  borrowers  is  equally  swift  and  effective.  The  mort- 
gage on  property  the  title  to  which  has  been  adjudicated  by 
the  process  described  makes  the  institution  practically  the 
owner  of  the  property  until  the  loan  is  conipletely  extin- 
guished.   It  has  the  right  to  take  possession  of  the  property 


PEINCIPLES   OF   LAND   CEEDIT  317 

upon  non-pajrment  of  a  defaulted  annuity  after  legal  demand 
without  appeal  to  the  courts  or  intervention  of  law.  The 
delinquent  cannot  dispute  the  records  of  the  mortgage  nor 
the  entries  in  the  books  of  the  institution.  Moreover,  no 
third  party  may  interfere.  The  claim  of  the  institution  takes 
precedence  over  every  other  claim  except  taxes,  and  even 
the  courts  cannot  issue  an  injunction  against  it.  The  institu- 
tion's of&cers  or  agents  have  powers  as  public  bailiffs  or  con- 
stables, and  may  hold  the  property  and  farm  or  rent  it  until 
the  defaulted  annuities  have  been  entirely  recovered.  If  this 
sequestration  is  not  effectual  in  realizing  the  claim,  the  insti- 
tution may  then  request  the  court  for  judgment  against  the 
debtor  and  an  order  of  sale  against  the  mortgaged  property. 
The  court  must  render  its  decision  summarily  upon  the  docu- 
mentary evidence  furnished  by  the  institution.  No  oral 
evidence  need  be  heard.  If  the  debtor  or  a  third  party  be 
aggrieved  his  remedy  lies  in  a  separate  suit  for  damages, 
in  which,  however,  this  decision  of  the  court  cannot  be  col- 
laterally attacked.  These  drastic  proceedings  for  the  recov- 
ery of  debts  are  not  allowed  private  land-credit  institutions, 
but  they  are  always  given  to  public  and  semi-public  insti- 
tutions and  landschafts.  They  may  be  resorted  to  not  only 
for  defaults  but  also  when  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  prop- 
erty becomes  impaired  or  the  borrower  violates  his  contract 
in  any  way. 

A  study  of  the  European  situation  shows  that  Germany, 
Sweden,  Denmark,  Switzerland  and  France  have  the  best 
systems  of  land  credit.  The  German  system  consists  of  pro- 
vincial landschafts,  provincial  public  banks,  and  land  mort- 
gage banks  organized  under  an  imperial  law.  Absolute  free- 
dom of  action  is  allowed  by  the  laws,  and  as  a  result  institu- 
tions of  every  known  variety  operate  side  by  side  in  Germany 
in  free  and  open  competition.  Land  credit  if  not  cheaper 
is  at  least  more  facile  there  than  in  any  other  country. 

In  Sweden  a  central  semi-public  institution,  created  by  a 
special  act,  operates  in  conjunction  vrith  ten  district  land- 
mortgage  associations  similarly  created,  and  none  other  may 
be  formed  without  the  consent  of  the  Crown.     The  central 


218  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

institution,  called  the  Swedish  General  Mortgage  Bank,  ad- 
vances money  to  the  district  associations  upon  the  assign- 
ment of  mortgages  which  the  associations  take  from  memhers. 
Members  of  each  association  are  joiutly  and  severally  liable 
for  the  money  so  received.  The  objectionable  feature  of  the 
Swedish  system  is  that  the  bank  is  too  closely  connected 
with  the  Government  and  enjoys  a  monopoly. 

In  Denmark  there  are  14  land  mortgage  associations  of 
the  landschaft  type  for  first  mortgages,  and  nine  for  second 
mortgages  on  small  estates.  The  Danish  associations  are  the 
best  adaptation  of  the  landschaft  outside  of  Germany.  The 
nine  associations  for  granting  loans  on  second  mortgage  on 
small  estates  are  the  only  ones  of  their  kind  in  Europe,  and 
the  only  other  country  in  which  their  practice  is  followed  is 
in  the  United  States,  by  the  Jewish  Agricultural  and  Indus- 
trial Aid  Society. 

In  Switzerland  there  are  semi-public  institutions  in  the 
various  cantons.  The  Land  Mortgage  Bank  of  Berne  is  the 
most  important.  It  requires  the  guaranty  of  a  commune  on 
every  loan  it  grants  to  an  individual.  Its  objectionable  fea- 
tures are  that  it  has  too  many  different  powers  and  that  the 
canton  is  a  part  owner  of  it. 

In  France  one  large  semi-public  institution  has  been  ac- 
corded such  valuable  special  privileges  that  it  has  been  able 
to  kiU  off  competition  and  obtain  a  practical  monopoly.  This 
institution  is  the  Credit  Foncier,  which  has  been  the  model 
in  Europe  for  nearly  all  central  la;nd-credit  banks  of  the 
joint-stock  variety.  The  appointment  of  the  president,  vice- 
presidents,  and  three  of  the  directors  by  the  state  assures  pub- 
licity and  honesty  in  management.  Its  objectionable  feature 
is  the  awarding  of  prizes  at  the  dravmig  of  debentures  for 
retirement. 

Institutions  available  for  landowners  in  restricted  areas 
exist  in  a  few  other  countries.  In  Eussia  there  is  a  land 
mortgage  association  of  the  landschaft  type  for  Finland,  a 
territorial  credit  institution  of  the  same  type  for  the  Baltic 
provinces  of  Livonia,  Esthonia  and  Kurland,  and  an  institu- 
tion for  granting  long-time  loans  to  noble  proprietors  in 


PEIKCIPLES   OP  LAND  CREDIT  SJ9 

Poland.  In  Austria-Himgary  there  are  several  associations 
of  the  landsehaft  type  which  cover  a  certain  portion  of  the 
dual  kingdom.  Northern  and  central  Italy  are  served  by 
one  large  joint-stock  mortgage  company  and  a  number  of 
benevolent  savings  banks.  The  Italian  laws  do  not  contem- 
plate monopoly.  However,  they  require  a  special  license 
for  each  bank  and  at  present  these  banks  monopolize  the 
field  in  their  respective  areas. 

Loans  granted  by  private  land-credit  institutions  as  a  rule 
are  in  cash,  but  those  granted  by  landschafts  are  in 
debentures  of  the  exact  amount  and  interest  rate  of  the  note 
and  mortgage  for  which  they  are  exchanged.  Semi-public 
land-credit  institutions  also  sometimes  make  loans  in  deben- 
tures. The  borrower  obligates  himself  to  pay  the  interest  of 
the  debentures  he  receives,  and  in  addition  thereto  his  share 
of  the  cost  of  running  the  landsehaft  and  keeping  up  the 
reserve  and  a  fraction  of  the  principal  of  his  loan  each 
year.  These  items  form  his  annuity,  which  is  divided  into 
halves  and  paid  semi-annually.  When  the  annuities  are  col- 
lected by  the  landsehaft  they  are  split  up  into  their  com- 
ponent parts  for  their  proper  uses,  and  the  fraction  of  the 
principal  which  the  borrower  pays  to  extinguish  his  debt  is 
placed  in  a  sinking  fund  for  the  amortization  of  the  deben- 
tures. Borrowers  have  the  right  to  hasten  the  extinction  of 
their  loans  by  making  voluntary  payments  into  the  sinking 
fund.  Moreover,  on  certain  conditions  they  may  withdraw 
the  balance  to  their  credit  in  the  sinking  fund  and  use  it  as  a 
new  loan,  thus  continually  renewing  their  credit  as  they 
please. 

This  sinking  fund  is  not  left  to  accumidate  until  it  equals 
the  aggregate  amount  of  a  series  or  any  given  amoxmt  of 
debentures,  but  every  six  months  a  drawing  is  made  and 
debentures  are  selected  by  lot,  according  as  their  numeros 
come  out  of  the  wheel,  for  retirement  up  to  the  amount  of 
money  on  hand  in  the  sinking  fund.  In  Italy  and  Japan 
debentures  must  be  withdrawn  not  only  up  to  the  amount  of 
money  on  hand  in?  the  sinking  fund,  but  also  up  to  that 
amount  as  increased  by  the  addition  of  the  amount  of  the 


220  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

defaults  of  debtors  during  the  preceding  six  months;  this 
■wise  provision  of  the  Italian  and  Japanese  laws  prevents  bad 
loans  from  long  being  used  as  security  for  debentures.  If  the 
sinking  fund  is  not  disposed  of  by  retiring  debentures,  it 
must  be  used  in  making  new  loans  or  in  buying  up  the 
institution's  own  debentures  for  cancellation  or  investment. 
Consequently,  there  is  no  cash  lying  idle  in  the  sinking  fund 
to  tempt  officials  into  speculative  ventures  or  into  carrying 
on  any  business  other  than  that  for  which  the  institution  is 
intended.  The  reserves  must  be  employed  in  the  same  way 
or  invested  in  bonds  of  the  Government,  municipalities  or 
government  railroads.  Eeserves  are  obligatory  for  aU  kinds 
of  institutions. 

By  reason  of  the  peculiar  method  of  making  loans,  the 
landschaft  does  not  need  to  have  a  capital  stock  or  to  keep 
large  funds  on  hand.  ISTor  is  it  necessary  for  it  to  hire  agents 
to  sell  its  debentures.  The  borrowers  act  as  its  agents,  except 
where  bureaus  have  been  opened  for  their  convenience.  The 
debentures  are  not  issued  in  series  but  bond  by  bond  as  mem- 
bers avail  themselves  of  their  credit;  thus  a  mortgage  loan 
is  taken  before  each  debenture  is  issued  and  the  retirement 
of  the  debentures  keeps  pace  with  the  paying  off  of  the  loans. 
Consequently,  the  face  value  of  the  debentures  in  circulation 
never  exceeds  the  amount  of  the  outstanding  loans.  The 
preservation  of  this  equilibrium  is  the  only  limit  fixed  for 
the  amount  of  the  loans  which  may  be  granted  or  the  deben- 
tures which  may  be  issued.  Within  this  limit  the  landschaft 
may  continue  its  operations  until  all  the  demands  in  its 
territory  have  been  supplied.  The  Danish  landschaft  associa- 
tions for  large  estates  arrange  their  members  ia  groups 
according  to  the  periods  in  which  they  join,  and  the  indi- 
viduals of  these  groups  are  severally  and  not  jointly  liable  on 
the  debentures  exchanged  for  their  own  loans  but  not  for  loans 
to  individuals  of  other  groups ;  to  that  extent  the  debentures 
in  Denmark  are  issued  serially. 

The  debentures  of  joint-stock  land-credit  institutions  are 
usually  issued  in  series,  authority  being  obtained  therefor 
from  the  Government  upon  resolution  of  the  board  of  direc- 


PEINCIPLES  OP  LAND   CEEDIT  221 

tors,  but  are  never  negotiated  in  advance  of  making  at  least 
an  equal  amount  of  loans.  The  rule  prescribed  for  the  land- 
schafts  for  preserviag  the  equilibrium  between  debentures  in 
circulation'  and  outstanding  loans  applies  also  to  them.  In 
addition  to  this  the  extreme  limit  of  debenture  issues  is  fixed 
at  a  certain  number  of  times  the  capital  stock  and  reserve. 
The  maximum  for  the  land  mortgage  banks  of  Germany 
is  15  times,  and  for  the  Credit  Foncier  of  France  20  times, 
the  capital  stock  and  reserve.  The  purpose  of  this  additional 
rule  is  to  prevent  a  company  from  becoming  too  large  to  be 
managed  properly  and  from  absorbing  the  entire  business  of 
the  country.  Usually  the  debentures  are  negotiated  to  recoup 
the  amount  taken  out  of  the  capital  stock  or  other  funds  of 
the  issuing  company  for  loans  already  made.  The  Credit 
Foncier  of  France,  however,  may  sell  debentures  for  the  pur- 
pose of  financing  loans  yet  to  be  made,  but  the  proceeds  of  the 
sales  must  be  invested  in  government  bonds  or  similar  safe 
security  pending  their  regular  employment. 

Loans  made  by  the  joint-stock  land-credit  institutions 
may  be  for  the  same  periods  and  for  the  same  amounts  in 
proportion  to  the  value  of  the  mortgaged  premises  as  those 
of  the  landschafts.  There  is  a  difference,  however,  in  the 
uses  made  of  the  annuities.  The  joint-stock  institutions 
usually  include  the  costs  of  business  in  the  computation  of 
the  interest  rate  and  always  deduct  a  portion  for  profits. 
Nevertheless,  the  actual  charge  to  borrowers  is  about  the 
same  in  both  kinds  of  institution.  This  is  due  to  the  fact 
that  any  advantage  which  the  landschafts  may  derive  from 
the  gratuitous  service  of  officers  and  the  compulsory  service 
of  members  is  offset  by  the  cumbersomeness  of  their  bureau- 
cratic methods  and  by  the  superior  energy  of  the  officials  of 
the  companies,  who  are  spurred  on  by  good  salaries  and  the 
demand  of  stockholders  for  dividends. 

The  regulations  in  respect  to  the  investment  of  the  sink- 
ing fund  and  the  retirement  of  debentures  are  the  same  for 
aU  concerns.  Debentures  must  in  all  events  be  redeemed  at 
par  regardless  of  their  market  quotation  at  the  date  of  issue 
or  redemption.     If  the  debentures  of  a  landschaft  are  dis- 


222  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

counted  below  par,  the  borrower  loses  the  amomit  of  the 
disagio ;  but,  if  a  company  negotiates  debentures  below  par,  it 
must  foot  the  loss,  of  course,  since  the  sales  are  made  on  its 
own  account  and  no.t  on  that  of  its  borrowers.  The  retire- 
ment of  debentures  by  drawing  lots  subjects  the  holders  to 
the  possibility  of  having  their  money  returned  to  them  when 
they  are  least  able  to  reinvest  it  profitably.  This  iaeonven- 
ience  is  compensated  in  some  countries  by  allowing  the  com- 
panies to  redeem  with  premiums.  The  Credit  Foncier  gives 
prizes;  this  is  one  of  the  special  privileges  which  make  this 
great  bank  the  dictator  of  land  credit  in  France. 

The  debentures  are  secured,  first,  by  the  mass  of  mort- 
gages taken  for  the  loans,  next  by  the  reserves  and  in  some 
instances  the  guaranty  fund,  and  finally  by  the  share  cap- 
ital in  the  joint-stock  companies,  by  the  collective  liability, 
limited  or  unlimited,  of  members  in  the  landschafts,  or  by 
the  guaranty  of  the  state  in  the  public  or  semi-public  insti- 
tutions. Sometimes  in  the  latter  institutions  a  fund  created 
by  subsidy  is  substituted  for  the  state  guaranty.  Inasmuch 
as  the  debentures  are  not  recallable  except  at  the  will  of  the 
makers,  the  holders  may  not  touch  the  principal  until  it  has 
been  declared  to  be  due  after  the  drawings,  and  even  then  they 
have  not  always  the  right  to  sue  the  institutions  for  it.  Some- 
times debentures  are  worded  to  be  redeemed  within  a  speci- 
fied period,  as  25,  50,  75  or  98  years,  but  this  does  not  alter 
their  effect.  The  assets,  including  the  annuities  due  from  the 
borrowers,  are  protected  from  all  litigation  except  bank- 
ruptcy proceedings.  The  debentures  are  merely  certificates 
of  indebtedness  secured  by  a  fioating  charge  against  the  gen- 
eral assets  and  standing  of  the  issuing  institution,  although 
in  the  event  of  the  winding  up  of  its  affairs,  they  would 
have  a  lien  prior  to  aU  other  of  its  creditors  on  the  mortgages 
used  as  the  basis  of  their  issue. 

The  imrecallable  long-term  debenture  is  absolutely  essen- 
tial to  the  according  of  long-term  credit.  No  concern  could 
grant  long-term  loans  if  it  were  required  to  retire  debentures 
at  a  faster  rate  than  it  can  refund  the  principal  by  the  annui- 
ties received  from  its  borrowers.     The  great  obstacle  to  the 


PEINCIPLES  OP  LAND  CEEDIT  233 

organization  of  land  credit  is  the  difficulty  of  popularizing 
the  unrecaUable  debentures,  of  selling  bonds  which  contain 
no  clause  obligating  the  maker  to  return  the  investment  to 
the  holder  at  some  jBxed  date.  With  the  view  of  overcoming 
this  difficulty,  aU  countries  have  surroimded  the  issue  of  these 
debentures  with  safeguards  and  attached  certain  privileges  to 
them  so  as  to  make  them  attractive  to  investors.  They  may 
be  drawn  in  denominations  as  small  as  $20,  payable  to  bearer 
or  in  the  name  of  the  holder  as  preferred,  and  may  be  pur- 
chased in  instalments.  As  a  rule  they  are  not  taxable  either 
at  issue  or  transfer.  Whenever  they  are  taxed,  it  is  done  in- 
directly by  taxing  the  institution  itself  on  the  total  amount 
of  debentures  issued  or  on  its  business  or  assets.  The  deben- 
tures are  exempt  from  seizure  and  sale  on  execution,  and  are 
usable  by  the  Government,  courts  and  trustees  for  investment 
of  all  kinds  of  funds.  The  debenture  is  considered  a  real- 
estate  security  to  the  same  extent  as  the  underlying  mort- 
gage and  far  superior  to  it  because  of  the  fact  that  the  deben- 
ture splits  up  the  loan  into  easily  negotiable  parts. 

Thus,  in  all  European  countries  where  land  credit  has 
been  organized,  the  safest  kind  of  securities  available  for 
large  and  small  investors  are  these  privileged  debentures  se- 
cured by  mortgages  on  properties  with  unassailable  titles,  or- 
dinarily worth  twice  the  face  value  of  the  mortgages.  The 
payment  of  interest  and  principal  is  assured  by  strict  govern- 
mental supervision  which  prevents  over-issue  and  which 
reserves  the  annuities  of  borrowers  for  their  ultimate  redemp- 
tion. The  older  the  debentures  become  the  sounder  they  are, 
because  of  the  fact  that  their  sinking  fund  is  constantly  in- 
creased by  the  annuities  paid  into  it,  or  else  that  the  liabil- 
ities of  the  institution  are  reduced  by  the  half-yearly  retire- 
ments of  other  debentures.  The  savings  of  the  poor  as  well 
as  those  of  the  rich  are  readily  attracted  by  these  absolutely 
safe  and  highly  negotiable  securities,  and  as  a  resiilt  there 
is  no  European  landschaft  or  semi-pubUe  land-credit  institu- 
tion which  does  not  find  all  the  funds  it  requires  at  the 
lowest  interest  rates  for  making  long-time  loans  to  its  bor- 
rowers.   Such  facilities,  however,  are  not  possible  at  present 


224  EUEAL    CREDITS 

in  the  United  States,  where  the  land,  the  mortgage,  and  the 
debenture  all  are  taxed.  This  triple  taxation  will  have  to  be 
removed  if  American  farmers  hope  to  obtain  cheap  land 
credit. 

Besides  this  favorable  legislation  for  debentures,  the  tax 
exemptions  and  the  special  proceedings  allowed  for  examining 
titles  and  recovering  loans,  some  of  the  land-credit  institu- 
tions have  been  granted  monopolies  and  many  are  allowed 
the  free  use  of  the  mails.  None  has  to  register  its  mort- 
gages every  ten  years  as  is  required  of  ordinary  lenders.  In 
France  the  Credit  Foncier  enjoys  the  free  service  of  the 
internal  revenue  officials  for  collecting  and  paying  interest, 
annuities,  and  principal  on  loans  and  debentures.  In  former 
times  subventions  were  frequent.  Some  of  the  landschafts 
of  Germany  and  Denmark,  the  Credit  Foncier  of  France,  the 
Mortgage  Bank  of  Berne,  not  to  mention  others,  received 
subsidies  from  the  state  at  their  establishment.  The  sub- 
sidies took  the  form  of  donations,  loans  without  iuterest,  the 
purchase  by  the  state  of  shares  of  the  capital  stock,  the 
guaranty  of  debentures,  or  the  investment  of  public  funds  in 
the  debentures.  But  financial  assistance  is  now  no  longer 
extended  except  to  institutions  organized  to  help  the  poor  to 
acquire  homes  or  small  tracts  of  agricultural  lands. 

In  the  United  States  there  is  not  a  peasantry  and  pro- 
letariat, except  possibly  among  the  southern  negroes,  so  weak 
and  benighted  as  to  need  free  money  and  state  aid  to  enable 
them  to  earn  a  living.  State  assistance  of  a  general  nature 
may  be  extended  without  objection  or  danger  in  the  early 
stages  of  the  organization  of  land  credit.  The  state  may  pre- 
side at  the  formation  and  even  assist  in  the  administration 
at  the  beginning  in  order  to  give  a  proper  direction  to  the 
development  of  land  credit.  It  is  clearly  the  state's  duty  to 
remove  all  obstacles  which  prevent  the  borrower  and  lender 
from  meeting  on  equal  terms,  and  it  should  continually  exer- 
cise rigorous  supervision  and  inspection  for  the  purpose  of 
safeguarding  borrowers  from  usurious  oppression  and  the 
investing  public  from  dishonest  and  incompetent  manage- 
ment.    The  state  may  intervene  in  the  event  of  overwhelm- 


PEINCIPLES   OF  LAND  CEEDIT  225 

ing  emergency  to  help  farmers  to  recover  from  the  effects  of 
droughts,  floods,  wars,  public  disorders,  and  widespread  devas- 
tations due  to  natural  causes,  or  to  finance  projects  too  great 
for  individual  enterprise,  such  as  the  reclamation  of  large 
areas  by  drainage  or  irrigation.  The  use  of  the  state's  guar- 
anty or  of  public  funds  for  ordinary  needs  of  farmers,  how- 
ever, would  be  class  legislation  which  would  work  an  injus- 
tice to  the  rest  of  the  population  and  sap  the  virility  of  the 
intended  beneficiaries.  In  nearly  all  countries  in  Europe 
where  direct  financial  aid  has  been  granted  it  has  led  to 
bureaucracy,  favoritism  and  politics.  The  sole  function  of 
the  government  in  a  republic  composed  of  intelligent  and  in- 
dependent citizens  should  be  to  open  the  way  for  entire  free- 
dom of  action  and  to  stimulate  private  initiative  and  compe- 
tition by  permitting  land-credit  institutions  of  various  kinds 
to  be  formed  under  general  laws. 

In  Europe  the  land-credit  institutions  of  the  joint-stock 
and  dividend-paying  type  which  grant  long-term  loans  are 
formed  along  the  general  lines  of  the  Credit  Poneier.  With 
a  few  ezceptions  the  scheme  of  organization  and  administra- 
tion and  the  business  methods  of  the  great  French  model 
have  been  more  or  less  closely  followed  by  all  of  them.  The 
ultimate  security  of  their  mortgage  bonds  or  debentures  is 
their  capital  stocks,  but  the  ultimate  security  of  the  deben- 
tures of  the  associations  of  borrowers  is  the  collective  lia- 
bility, limited  or  unlimited,  of  members.  These  associations 
are  of  two  classes,  those  which  are  private  groups  of  indi- 
vidual borrowers  without  any  special  privileges  or  connec- 
tion with  the  government,  and  those  which  are  semi-public 
or  public  in  character  and  possess  all  the  various  privileges 
which  have  been  devised  to  facilitate  land  credit.  The  orig- 
inals of  the  latter  are  the  Prussian  landschafts,  with  which 
the  idea  of  collective  liabUity  of  borrowers  and  also  of  the 
debenture  was  conceived.  The  collective  liability  of  groups 
of  borrowers  has  proved  satisfactory  and  popular  wherever 
employed.  The  Prussian  landschafts  are  generally  recognized 
as  nearly  perfect  in  respect  to  organization  and  administra- 
tion, while  it  is  also  believed  that  if  their  business  methods 


226  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

■were  modernized  and  made  less  ciimbersome,  they  ■would  be 
the  best  institutions  in  Europe  for  according  long-time  credit 
on  large  or  small  farms. 

Could  landschafts  be  instituted  in  the  United  States? 
Is  there  a  field  for  extensive  operations  and  usefulness  for 
such  organizations,  the  oldest  of  land-credit  institutions, 
■which  have  been  diffusing  long-term  credit  on  farm  lands  in 
Prussia  for  a  century  and  a  half,  have  spread  over  almost 
all  of  Germany,  S^weden  and  Denmark,  and  have  been  intro- 
duced in  other  European  countries?  The  question  deserves 
an  answer  because  no  landsehaft  has  ever  failed  and  all  have 
been  able  to  find  credit  for  their  members  at  the  lowest  inter- 
est rates  and  easiest  terms.  The  answer  can  be  best  arrived 
at  by  recapitulating  the  description  already  given  of  the 
Silesian  landsehaft,  the  first  one  formed,  and  then  trying 
to  see  ■whether  in  theory  a  similar  institution  could  be  adapted 
to  any  state  of  the  Union.  Kansas,  ■where  agrieidture  ■was 
demoralized  in  part  20  years  ago  by  faulty  methods  of  credit, 
may  be  used  for  this  purpose,  ia  comparison  ■with  Silesia, 
■where  farmers  are  able  to  obtain  long-term  credit  on  the 
easiest  terms  through  the  landsehaft  ■which  has  been  operating 
■with  uninterrupted  success  since  1770. 

The  Silesian  landsehaft  is  not  a  joint-stock  company  or 
even  an  association,  properly  speaking.  It  is  a  financial 
system  created  by  the  state  and  made  a  part  of  the  state,  but 
the  state  receives  no  dividends  or  compensation  from  it,  since 
any  profits  made  are  devoted  to  paying  off  the  principal  or 
reducing  the  interest  of  the  loans  of  borro^wers.  Its  sole 
object  is  to  find  cheap  long-term  credit  for  farmers,  and  with 
this  in  view  it  strives  to  make  the  debentures  which  it  is 
authorized  to  issue  the  safest  securities  which  can  be  bought 
in  the  market.  Silesia  is  divided  for  the  administrative  pur- 
poses of  the  system  into  nine  districts  which  in  their  turn  are 
subdivided  into  two  or  more  circles,  in  much  the  same  way 
as  Kansas  is  divided  into  districts  and  counties  for  judicial 
purposes. 

The  head  of  a  circle  is  a  superintendent  elected  by  mem- 
bers of  the  system  residing  within  the  circle.     The  head  of 


PEINCIPLES  OP  LAND  CEEDIT  2%t 

a  district  is  a  manager  appointed  by  the  Crown  upon  nomi- 
nation of  the  members  of  the  district.  The  head  of  the  entire 
system  is  the  president  appointed  by  the  Crown  upon  the 
nomination  of  all  members  voting  by  districts.  Associated 
with  him  are  three  vice-presidents  similarly  appointed.  The 
president  and  vice-presidents  with  two  general  counselors 
selected  by  them  constitute  the  executive  council,  which  passes 
finally  upon  the  loans  applied  for  by  members,  and  makes 
them  by  exchanging  the  landschaff  s  debentures  for  the  bor- 
rowers' notes  and  mortgages.  Each  district  has  a  district 
board  composed  of  the  manager,  the  superintendents  of  the 
circles  and  a  lawyer  selected  by  them  for  its  attorney.  The 
boards  pass  in  the  first  instance  on  all  applications  for  loans 
coming  from  persons  within  their  respective  areas,  and  attend 
to  the  sequestration  of  properties  and  foreclosures  of  mort- 
gages in  cases  of  defaults.  In  each  circle  there  are  periodical 
meetings  presided  over  by  the  superintendent,  and  at  which  all 
borrowers  who  are  not  in  default  on  their  mortgages  or  who 
have  not  violated  their  contracts  in  any  way  are  entitled  to 
be  present  and  vote  as  members. 

The  business  and  affairs  of  the  SUesian  landschaft  are 
conducted  by  these  official  central  and  district  bodies.  AU 
owners  of  farm  lands  within  the  area  over  which  the  land- 
schaft exercises  jurisdiction  have  right  to  become  members  of 
the  system,  but  members  have  nothing  to  do  with  the  ad- 
mission or  expulsion  of  members  or  with  the  granting,  re- 
caUing  or  renewing  of  credit.  Their  powers  are  confined 
to  voting  at  the  elections  for  ofBeers  and  for  delegates  to 
the  general  assembly  of  the  landschaft,  upon  resolutions  sub- 
mitted to  them  from  the  boards  or  council,  upon  the  annual 
budget,  and  upon  the  question  of  raising  funds  for  the  land- 
schaft when  necessary.  The  landschaft,  however,  rarely  needs 
money.  Members  may  be  eompulsorUy  required  to  act  as 
appraisers  or  caretakers  of  any  properties  falling  into  the 
possession  of  the  landschaft,  under  pain  of  having  their  loans 
recalled  in  case  of  refusal  so  to  act. 

The  supreme  authority  in  the  landschaft  is  the  general 
assembly.     This  body  is  composed  not  of  members  but  of 


228  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

delegates  elected  by  the  members.  It  is  convened  only  upon 
emergencies  and  is  represented  in  the  interim  by  a  perma- 
nent committee  composed  of  the  executive  coimcil,  the  dis- 
trict managers,  and  a  delegate  from  each  of  the  districts 
elected  by  the  members  thereof.  The  landsehaft  is  subject  to 
the  general  supervision  of  the  Minister  of  Agriculture 
through  a  special  commissioner  who  makes  regular  inspec- 
tions and  receives  the  annual  reports.  Full  particulars  of 
the  powers  and  duties  of  the  officials  as  well  as  the  steps 
which  members  may  take  on  their  own  initiative  for  certaiu 
purposes  may  be  obtained  by  rereading  the  description  of 
this  Silesian  landsehaft.  It  must  be  remembered  that  the 
landsehaft  does  not  make  loans  in  cash.  It  simply  issues 
guaranteed  debentures  to  borrowers  on  their  notes  and  mort- 
gages and  undertakes  to  collect  the  borrowers'  annuities  and 
pay  to  the  holders  of  the  debentures  the  interest  and  priu- 
eipal  as  they  become  due.  The  debentures  are  of  two  kinds, 
on  one  of  which  the  members  are  collectively  liable  without 
limit,  while  on  the  other  this  liability  extends  only  to  the 
members  of  the  respective  districts. 

Now  if  Kansas  should  adopt  the  landsehaft,  it  could  have 
two  landschafts  each  operating  over  an  area  at  least  equal  to 
that  of  Silesia,  but  preferably  it  should  have  but  one,  under 
the  supervision  of  the  state  bank  examiner.  The  law  enacted 
for  its  establishment  would  divide  the  state  into  20  districts, 
assigning  to  each  district  about  four  counties,  and  provide  for 
the  election  of  the  necessary  officials  to  be  appointed  every 
six  years  by  the  Governor  upon  nomination  of  the  members 
of  the  system,  exactly  in  the  way  in  which  this  is  done  in 
Silesia.  These  officials  would  serve  without  pay,  and  after 
the  first  term  they  would  be  selected  from  among  the  bor- 
rowers of  the  system.  All  resident  citizens  who  owned 
farm  lands  free  and  clear  of  encumbrance  would  be  allowed 
to  obtain  debentures  from  the  landsehaft  up  to  two-thirds 
the  value  of  the  mortgaged  property.  The  law  should  contain 
a  provision  that  it  could  not  become  operative  in  any  dis- 
trict except  upon  the  request  of  farmers  with  properties  of 
an  aggregate  value  of,  say,  $1,000,000. 


PKINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CREDIT  229 

All  borrowers  would  be  made  collectively  liable  without 
limit  for  debentures  issued  to  members  withia  their  districts. 
A  person  would  become  a  member  upon  obtaining  this  credit, 
and  his  mortgage  would  be  so  drawn  as  to  give  the  landschaft 
immediate  possession  ia  case  of  default  or  whenever  the  land- 
schaft should  deem  its  security  impaired  or  insufficient. 
Upon  the  extraction  of  his  debt  a  borrower's  liability  would 
cease  along  with  his  membership.  The  expenses  of  the  land- 
schaft would  be  met  by  a  small  percentage  added  to  the  in- 
terest rate.  Each  borrower  also  would  be  required  to  pay  a 
fraction  of  his  principal  every  half-year,  and  also  a  small 
contribution  for  forming  a  reserve  which  eventually  would 
become  large  enough  to  cover  all  possible  losses  and  save  bor- 
rowers from  ever  being  assessed  on  their  collective  liability. 
The  reserve  and  the  sinking  fund  would  have  to  be  invested 
in  debentures  of  the  landschaft  or  in  bonds  of  the  state,  mu- 
nicipalities or  public  corporations  in  Kansas.  The  sinking 
fund  would  be  employed  every  half-year  in  paying  off  deben- 
tiires  retired  from  circulation  by  drawing  lots. 

So  this  system  of  land  credit,  if  adopted  for  Kansas, 
would  not  call  for  any  subsidy,  expenditure,  guaranty  or  lia- 
bility on  the  part  of  the  state  or  any  subdivision  of  the  state. 
It  would  be  based  on  the  security  of  the  combined  farm  lands 
only  of  the  persons  who  might  wish  to  use  the  system's  credit 
facilities,  and  would  enable  the  Kansas  farmers  to  convert 
all  their  three-  and  five-year  mortgage  loans  into  long-time 
annuity  contracts  running  for  any  periods  they  desired,  even 
up  to  75  or  100  years,  and  repayable  out  of  the  annual  farm 
profits  at  a  rate  of  interest  as  low  as  that  at  which  the  state 
itself  can  borrow  money.  Surely  the  landschaft  idea  will  be 
introduced  sooner  or  later  into  some  of  the  states  of  the 
United  States,  either  as  private  or  semi-public  institutions, 
in  view  of  the  fact  that  it  has  proved  its  efficacy  for  easy 
long-term  credit  for  farmers  in  eight  European  coimtries. 

Wisconsin  passed  a  Land  Mortgage  Associations  Act  in. 
1913  which  has  been  widely  heralded  as  a  step  towards  the 
organization  of  land  credit  on  correct  principles  for  agri- 
culture and  cooperation.     The  Act,  however,  is  nothing  of 


230  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  sort  and  adds  very  little  to  legislation  on  the  subject 
already  existing  in  the  state.  The  associations  contemplated 
by  this  Act  are  mere  private  corporations  with  fixed  capital 
of  a  minimxun  of  $10,000  divided  into  $100  shares.  Their 
powers  are  to  issue  bonds  on  the  pledge  of  first  mortgages 
given  as  security  for  loans  on  farm  lands,  forests  and  dwell- 
ing houses  located  within  Wisconsin.  The  loans  are  not 
confined  to  shareholders  but  may  be  granted  to  any  com- 
petent person  offering  such  security.  Hence  the  associations 
are  not  landschafts  or  associations  of  borrowers,  nor  are  they 
even  cooperative,  but  are  simply  plain  bond  and  mortgage 
companies. 

The  bonds,  the  circulation  of  which  for  each  company 
is  restricted  to  20  times  its  capital  and  surplus,  have  been 
made  legal  investments  for  trustee  funds  and  public  moneys 
and  may  not  be  taxed  if  the  taxes  on  the  mortgaged  prop- 
erties have  been  paid  by  the  mortgagor  or  the  company.  The 
other  provisions  of  the  Act  are  of  doubtful  value.  The 
property  offered  in  security  must  be  appraised  by  two  free- 
holders residing  in  its  locality  appointed  by  the  directors,  and 
the  appraisal  must  be  certified  by  the  assessor  of  incomes 
as  not  being  over  the  true  market  value.  The  expenses  of 
the  assessor  are  paid  by  the  borrower.  Now  as  no  private 
money  lender,  bank  or  ordinary  company  would  take  a  secur- 
ity without  making  an  investigation  in  person  or  by  in- 
spectors paid  by  itself  and  over  whom  it  had  absolute  control, 
this  provision  standing  alone  has  a  bad  effect,  because  it 
might  tempt  the  committee  on  loans  into  taking  a  security 
recommended  as  a  perfunctory  act  by  persons  in  no  wise 
connected  with  the  company  or  interested  in  its  success. 
Again,  the  notes  and  mortgages  used  as  security  for  bonds 
must  be  placed  in  trust  with  the  state  treasurer.  This  slight 
precaution  against  possible  dishonesty  of  the  company's  ofiB- 
cials  or  clerks  adds  nothing  to  the  soundness  of  mortgages 
already  duly  filed  and  recorded.  It  would  have  been  a  great 
deal  better  if  private  persons  had  been  designated  as  the 
trustees,  thus  guarding  the  public  from  being  misled  into 
believing  that  the  state  was  back  of  the  bonds. 


PEINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT  231 

The  wisdom  of  aUowing  little  bond  and  mortgage  com- 
panies to  parade  in  the  garb  of  officiality  may  be  seriously 
questioned,  especially  when,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Wisconsin 
so-caUed  associations,  they  intend  to  grant  long-term  loans 
without  adequate  assurances  in.  law  for  their  endurance  or 
the  integrity  of  their  capital  stock  and  reserves.  No  regula- 
tion exists  in  Wisconsin  for  the  fluid  iuvestment  of  the 
reserves.  In  Europe  all  companies  have  substantial  capital 
stock  and  all  associations  are  composed  of  members  whose 
combined  properties  aggregate  many  hundreds  of  thousands 
of  doUars.  The  auditors  iu  Wisconsin  are  appointed  by  the 
shareholders.  In  the  best  European  systems  the  auditors 
are  public  officials  or  else  are  so  appointed  that  as  a  matter 
of  course  they  favor  the  bondholders  and  borrowers  as  against 
the  shareholders  and  the  company. 

Fortunately  for  Wisconsiu,  however,  the  Act  contains  a 
few  sentences,  inadvertently  inserted,  which  makes  it 
practically  inoperative.  No  loan  may  be  granted  except 
with  an  annual  amortization  of  at  least  one  per  cent  of  the 
principal,  that  is,  assuming  that  applicants  for  loans  would 
insist  upon  the  average  rate  in  Wisconsin  of  five  per  cent  com- 
pounded on  their  instalment  payments,  a  loan  which  must 
run  for  no  shorter  period  than  36  years.  A  company,  par- 
ticularly a  small  one,  dealing  exclusively  in  that  kind  of  busi- 
ness cannot  give  that  rate  to  borrowers  for  their  instalment 
payments  and  at  the  same  time  distribute  satisfactory  divi- 
dends and  set  aside  out  of  its  profits  each  year  an  amount 
equal  to  two  per  cent  of  its  capital  stock  as  required  by  the 
Act.  If  it  cannot  distribute  satisfactory  dividends  it  cannot 
sell  its  shares,  while  if  it  does  not  accumulate  a  reserve  the 
public  will  become  distrustful  of  its  bonds.  Again,  the  Act 
abolishes  the  usury  laws  for  the  so-called  associations  by 
allowing  them  absolute  discretion  in  imposing  fines  on  bor- 
rowers for  defaults.  Borrowers  will  never  place  themselves 
at  the  mercy  of  such  an  association  if  they  can  find  a  lender 
elsewhere.  Equally  unfavorable  to  the  borrower  is  another 
provision  which  prevents  his  selling  his  property  when  once 
he  has  mortgaged  it  to  the  association  unless  he  can  find  a 


232  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

purchaser  who  will  assume  personal  responsibility  for  his 
debt.  As  a  rule  in  the  United  States  a  purchaser  acquires 
only  the  equity  of  a  mortgaged  property  and  incurs  thereby 
no  personal  liability  for  the  debt  of  the  mortgagor,  and  this 
custom  would  be  hard  to  change. 

In  1914  the  laws  of  New  York  on  saviags  and  loan  asso- 
ciations were  amended  to  enable  the  associations  in  operation 
to  establish  the  Land  Bank  of  the  State  of  New  York,  with 
headquarters  in  New  York  City.  Savings  and  loan  asso- 
ciations have  a  variable  capital  consisting  of  dues  and  divi- 
dends credited  to  members,  either  individually  or  in  series, 
and  divided  into  shares  of  $100  to  $200.  They  may  be 
formed  for  encouraging  thrift  and  home-building,  accumu- 
lating savings  and  lending  such  accumulations  to  members. 

Instalment  shares,  savings  shares,  accumulative  prepaid 
shares,  income  shares,  and  juvenile-savings  shares,  or  any 
of  these  kinds,  may  be  issued  at  any  time  by  an  association 
called  permanent.  A  serial  association  must  issue  its  instal- 
ment shares  in  series  and  credit  by  series  the  dividends  ap- 
portioned to  such  shares,  and  no  additional  shares  may  be 
issued  in  any  series  after  a  dividend  has  been  once  credited 
thereto,  unless  the  subscriber  pays  the  book  value  of  such 
shares,  together  with  all  dues  owing  and  accrued  interest,  so 
as  to  place  the  original  subscribers  and  himself  on  a  par. 
The  method  and  length  of  time  for  maturing  the  shares  of  all 
kinds  are  determined  by  the  by-laws.  An  entrance,  member- 
ship or  transfer  fee  may  be  charged,  but  in  no  case  may  it 
exceed  one  dollar  per  member  or  share.  The  fines  which 
may  be  imposed  for  neglect  or  refusal  to  pay  dues,  interest,  or 
premiums  may  not  exceed  two  per  cent  a  month.  A  member 
who  is  not  a  borrower  may  withdraw  all  accumulations  on  his 
shares  after  sixty  days'  notice.  No  penalties  may  be  imposed 
for  withdrawing.  If  receipts  are  not  sufficient  to  meet  ma- 
turities and  withdrawals,  the  board  of  directors  or  the  Su- 
perintendent of  Banks  may  direct  all  claims  to  be  paid  upon 
a  ratable  and  proportionate  basis.  Thus  the  associations 
operate  with  funds  all  coming  from  members  and  subject  to 
comparatively  short  call.    A  member  must  subscribe  for  at 


PEINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT  233 

least  one  share;  he  may  hold  more  and  vote  them  all  if  the 
by-laws  permit.  Each  association  is  managed  by  directors 
elected  by  members.  A  guaranty  fund  must  be  created  ulti- 
mately to  equal  five  per  cent  of  its  accumulated  capital  and 
at  least  50  per  cent  of  the  value  of  any  real  estate  it  holds. 

Credit  may  be  accorded  only  to  members.  A  loan  may 
be  granted  on  one  or  more  than  one  of  the  various  kinds  of 
shares  if  its  amount  does  not  exceed  their  withdrawal  value. 
As  a  rule,  however,  loans  are  made  upon  mortgage  security, 
the  borrower  at  the  same  time  pledging  to  the  association  in- 
stalment shares  having  a  matured  value  at  least  equal  to  the 
amount  of  his  loan.  The  dues  on  these  shares,  payable  at 
regular  intervals  specified  in  the  by-laws,  and  the  dividends 
thereon  are  applied  in  reduction  of  his  indebtedness. 

The  property  ofEered  as  security  must  be  situated  within 
fifty  miles  of  the  headquarters  of  the  association.  No  loan 
may  exceed  75  per  cent  of  the  appraised  value.  An  associa- 
tion may  lend  up  to  the  maximum  on  improved  properties. 
Land  is  considered  improved  if  the  improvements  equal  the 
land  alone  in  value.  It  may  lend  up  to  60  per  cent  of  the 
value  of  unimproved  properties.  Land  is  considered  unim- 
proved if  the  value  of  the  improvements  does  not  equal  that  of 
the  land.  It  may  lend  up  to  only  50  per  cent  of  the  value 
of  vacant  properties.  Land  is  considered  vacant  if  there  is  no 
building  upon  it  suitable  for  residence,  business,  manufactur- 
ing or  agricultural  purposes.  In  such  case  the  money  bor- 
rowed may  be  used  only  for  erecting  such  a  building  and  is 
to  be  advanced  as  the  work  progresses.  The  total  loans  on 
vacant  lands  must  not  exceed  15  per  cent  of  the  accumulated 
capital  of  the  association. 

The  yearly  payments  of  dues  and  interest  required  on  a 
loan  in  excess  of  70  per  cent  of  the  appraised  value  must  not 
be  less  than  12  per  cent  of  the  principal.  At  6  per  cent  this 
would  mean  139  monthly  instalments,  if  the  interest  be 
charged  on  the  balance,  or  144  instalments,  if  interest  be 
charged  on  the  face  of  the  loan;  or  an  extreme  period  of  13 
years.  The  yearly  payments  of  dues  and  interest  must  be  not 
less  than  9  per  cent  of  the  principal,  if  the  amount  loaned 


234  KTJEAL   CEEDITS 

is  in  excess  of  60  per  cent,  and  not  over  70  per  cent  of  the 
appraised  value.  This  gives  an  extreme  period  of  about  18 
years.  No  minimum  is  prescribed  for  the  yearly  payments 
on  loans  whose  amounts  are  below  60  per  cent  of  the  ap- 
praised value  of  the  mortgaged  property:  consequently  the 
annual  payments  and  length  of  time  of  the  loan  may  be  left 
to  contract  between  the  association  and  the  borrowers.  The 
total  expenses  of  an  association  must  not  exceed  2.5  per  cent 
of  the  annual  dues  actually  received  from  members. 

The  money  available  for  loans  may  be  auctioned  to  the 
highest  bidder  upon  premium  plans  specified  in  the  law, 
which  thus  permits  an  association  to  charge  interest  higher 
than  the  legal  rate.  If  an  association  has  more  money 
than  it  needs  for  loans,  it  may  compel  members  to  accept 
the  withdrawal  value  of  their  shares,  or  it  may  invest  the 
surplus  in  loans  to  other  savings  and  loan  associations,  in 
securities  authorized  as  investments  for  savings  banks,  or  in 
first  mortgages  on  real  estate  in  New  Jersey.  The  last  pro- 
vision was  inserted  through  the  influence  of  New  Jersey 
suburbanites  who  work  in  New  York  City. 

These,  in  brief,  were  the  statutory  powers  and  methods  of 
New  York  savings  and  loan  associations  up  to  the  year  1914. 
There  are  in  operation  (1914)  241  associations  with  161,880 
members  and  $64,249,990  of  resources.  With  three  or  four 
exceptions  they  are  as  sound  as  any  institutions,  large  or  small, 
in  the  state.  They  are  the  survivors  of  many  associations 
which  were  formed  under  bad  laws  subsequently  repealed, 
and  managed  on  wrong  principles  at  last  abolished.  Chief 
among  the  objectionable  features  of  the  old  laws  was  the 
provision  giving  an  association  a  free  hand  to  operate 
throughout  the  state.  The  surviving  associations  are  local; 
moreover,  they  are  urban,  their  members  living  or  working 
in  the  towns  and  cities  and  their  assets  being  invested  in 
mortgages  on  urban  properties  and  in  liquid  securities.  The 
great  majority  of  members  are  not  borrowers,  and  the  non- 
borrowers  in  ordinary  times  by  their  savings  supply  the  asso- 
ciations with  all  the  money  needed  for  borrowing  members. 
For  emergencies  the  associations  themselves  may  borrow  for 


PEINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT  235 

terms  of  one  year  or  less,  provided  they  do  not  allow  their 
liabilities  to  outsiders  to  exceed  one-fifth  of  their  acciumilated 
capital.  This  would  seem  to  be  the  widest  limit  compatible 
with  safety.  It  has  proved,  however,  entirely  safe;  the  asso- 
ciations have  kept  well  within  it,  borrowing  only  to  relieve 
stringencies,  easily  paying  off  their  debts  as  they  faU  due, 
uniformly  distributing  much  larger  dividends  than  the  sav- 
ings banks,  and  charging  interest  on  loans  at  a  lower  rate 
than  the  average  lender.  Year  by  year  the  associations  in- 
creased steadily  in  number  and  wealth.  The  law  under 
which  they  operated,  particularly  with  this  wise  restriction 
against  incurring  heavy  outside  liabilities,  was  considered 
one  of  the  best  of  its  kind,  and  there  was  no  necessity  or  even 
an  intimation  of  a  demand  for  its  change  among  the  mass 
of  members. 

The  amendment  of  1914,  creating  the  Land  Bank,  has 
wrought  vital  changes  ia  the  New  York  law.  It  provides  that 
the  Land  Bank  may  be  organized  by  ten  or  more  associations 
with  aggregate  resources  of  not  less  than  $5,000,000,  and 
may  be  opened  for  business  when  $100,000  of  capital  has  been 
subscribed.  The  first  ten  associations  which  get  together 
may  enact  the  by-laws  of  the  Bank,  to  be  submitted  to  the 
State  Superintendent  of  Banks,  which  must  prescribe  the 
manner  of  caUing  meetings,  the  number  to  -constitute  a 
quorum,  the  duties  of  the  ofBcers,  and  the  manner  of  their 
election,  and  their  terms  of  office.  The  by-laws  when  once 
adopted  can  be  changed  only  by  resolution  of  the  directors 
approved  by  the  Superintendent  of  Banks.  Shareholders 
have  absolutely  no  initiative  in  this  matter  or  right  of  par- 
ticipation in  the  management,  while  it  is  possible  under  the 
law  for  the  original  incorporators  so  to  word  the  by-laws  as 
to  make  the  first  directors  self-perpetuating  for  many  years. 
This  could  be  done  also  by  any  subsequent  board  of  directors. 
Hence  the  Land  Bank  of  New  York  is  not  cooperative  in 
organization  or  administration,  although  its  membership  is 
eclectic  and  only  savings  and  loan  associations  may  be  share- 
holders. It  is  a  domestic  moneyed  corporation  with  a  vari- 
able capital  stock;  when  once  it  is  organized  under  the  law, 


236  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

no  other  land  bank  may  be  organized,  so  it  has  an  exclusive 
monopoly  of  its  field.  Nor  is  it  cooperative  in  objects  since 
it  has  power  to  do  a  general  loan  business  in  first  mortgages 
on  real  estate  in  New  York  and  New  Jersey  and  to  receive 
money  and  property  from  shareholders  and  all  other  persons 
with  whom  it  has  contracts,  engagements  or  undertakings. 
Its  loans  to  non-members  may  equal  in  amount  60  per  cent 
of  the  appraised  value  of  the  mortgaged  properties :  loans  to 
shareholders  may  equal  75  per  cent  of  the  appraised  value. 

The  Land  Bank  of  New  York  may  issue  bonds  but  only 
upon  notes  secured  by  first  mortgages  made  to  or  held  by 
shareholders  and  placed  in  trust  with  the  State  Comptroller. 
The  face  value  of  the  bonds  must  not  exceed  80  per  cent  of 
the  value  of  the  imderlying  mortgages  and  the  total  in  circu- 
lation, including  other  indebtedness,  must  not  exceed  20 
times  the  amount  of  the  capital  of  the  Bank,  presumably  the 
paid-in  capital,  although  the  law  is  not  clear  on  this  poiiit. 
The  bonds  are  exempt  from  taxation,  as  is  the  Bank  itself  to 
the  same  extent  as  a  savings  bank.  A  portion  of  the  profits 
equal  to  one-half  of  one  per  cent  of  the  capital  must  be  set 
aside  each  year  for  creating  a  guaranty  fund  idtimately 
equal  to  15  per  cent  of  the  capital,  but  inasmuch  as  the  direc- 
tors may  invest  this  fund  in  mortgages  there  is  no  superiority 
in  it  over  the  capital  as  obligatory  security  for  bondholders. 

The  amendment  of  the  law  to  enable  the  Land  Bank 
of  New  York  to  sell  its  shares  to  savings  and  loan  associa- 
tions, and  to  acquire  the  mortgages  securing  the  savings  of 
the  members  of  such  associations  for  use  as  security  for  its 
own  bonds  issued  for  sale  to  the  public,  does  not  affect  the 
manner  of  making  loans  except  in  one  minor  particular,  but 
it  makes  important  changes  in  the  regulations  relating  to  the 
investment  of  the  savings  of  their  individual  members.  For- 
merly the  law  permitted  loans  to  members  only  and  on  secur- 
ities, apart  from  mortgages,  authorized  for  savings  banks. 
Now,  however,  a  savings  and  loan  association  may  invest  10 
per  cent  of  the  members'  savings  and  its  other  resources  in 
shares  of  the  Land  Bank,  besides  buying  bonds  of  this  insti- 
tution with  any  funds  not  needed  for  loans  to  members.    In 


PEINCIPLES  OF  LAND  CEEDIT  237 

addition,  an  association,  if  it  has  no  debts  or  second  mort- 
gages, may  pledge  or  assign  75  per  cent  of  its  mortgages  and 
securities  either  for  cash  or  bonds  of  the  Land  Bank,  or  its 
entire  assets  if  members  wlII  assume  joint  and  general  un- 
limited liability  on  the  bonds.  But  the  total  liability  to  the 
Land  Bank  must  not  exceed  20  times  ten  per  cent  of  the 
accumulated  capital  of  the  association. 

Now  since  these  mortgages,  which  represent  the  savings 
of  members,  are  at  present  the  soundest  kind  of  investment 
and  at  the  same  time  bear  a  higher  interest  than  the  bonds 
of  the  Land  Bank  are  likely  to  bear  and  are  as  profitable 
as  any  safe  investments  which  can  be  made  out  of  the  asso- 
ciations' funds,  what  object  has  the  amendment  of  the  law 
in  authorizing  such  exchange  or  conversion?  If  an  associa- 
tion has  more  savings  than  it  can  invest  in  loans  to  mem- 
bers, it  is  justified  in  seeking  a  safe  investment  for  the  sur- 
plus, but  it  cannot  find  a  safer  investment  than  the  secur- 
ities authorized  for  savings  banks.  This  is  the  logical  impli- 
cation of  the  clause  in  the  law  which  requires  the  Land  Bank 
itself  to  use  those  securities  in  like  case.  If  an  association 
needs  cash  in  a  stringency  to  meet  liabilities  to  members,  it 
wotdd  be  good  business,  of  course,  temporarily  to  hypothe- 
cate a  portion  of  its  assets  to  raise  the  necessary  funds  for 
that  purpose;  but  since  an  association  must  buy  one  dollar 
of  shares  for  every  20  dollars  of  bonds  issued  by  the  Land 
Bank  in  its  behalf,  and  since  each  share  is  $1,000  and  only 
ten  per  cent  of  the  resources  of  the  association  may  be  in- 
vested in  shares,  an  association  in  a  stringency  would  be  likely 
to  find  the  services  of  the  Land  Bank  of  less  practical  value, 
than  those  of  an  ordinary  lender. 

Another  purpose  for  which  an  association  might  possibly 
resort  to  the  Land  Bank  of  New  York  is  for  raising  money 
with  which  to  make  new  loans.  But  in  this  case  it  would 
place  the  funds  of  the  Land  Bank  in  competition  vrith  the 
savings  of  its  ovm  members  and  reduce  their  dividends.  A 
loan,  it  will  be  remembered,  must  be  secured,  in  addition  to 
a  mortgage,  by  instalment  shares  subscribed  by  the  bor- 
rower and  having  a  matured  value  at  least  equal  to  the 


238  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

amount  of  his  loan,  and  these  shares  may  participate  fully 
in  all  dividends  while  shares  of  other  kinds  have  only  a  re- 
stricted participation.  Hence  the  tendency  would  he  for  in- 
vesting and  saving  members  to  drop  out  and  borrowing  mem- 
bers to  come  in.  This  tendency  undoubtedly  would  become 
pronoimced  in  an  association  which  should  go  the  legal  limit, 
put  ten  per  cent  of  its  resources  in  shares  of  the  Land  Bank, 
pledge  or  assign  to  the  Bank  75  per  cent  or  more  of  its 
holdings  of  mortgages  and  securities,  and  guarantee  bonds 
received  therefor  up  to  30  times  what  it  had  invested  in 
shares.  What  opportunity  for  the  profitable  investment  of 
the  savings  of  members  would  be  left  to  an  association  which 
operated  to  this  extent  on  funds  of  the  Land  Bank?  With 
the  incentive  to  thrift  thus  weakened  and  only  borrowing 
members  remaining,  the  association  would  lose  its  cooperative 
character  unless  the  borrowers  should  assume  joint  and  sev- 
eral liability  for  one  another's  loans. 

The  case  is  put  in  this  extreme  way  merely  to  elucidate 
the  principles  involved,  without  any  intention  to  imply  that 
there  may  be  positive  dangers  in  the  law.  Nevertheless  it 
must  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  New  York  savings  and  loan 
associations  are  now  automatically  safe  and  sound,  while,  if 
they  should  enter  into  relations  with  the  Land  Bank,  their 
future  would  become  involved  with  that  of  an  institution 
whose  success  depends  upon  honest,  conservative  and  efiBcient 
management.  EfiBcient  management  of  such  an  ambitious  ' 
financial  corporation  can  be  obtained  only  by  the  payment 
of  liberal  salaries  and  other  large  outlays.  The  law  recog- 
■  nizes  this  fact  by  providing  that  the  Land  Bank  may  charge 
shareholders  a  commission  of  one-half  of  one  per  cent  and 
redeem  its  bonds  at  103.5  per  cent.  These  expenses  and 
commissions  must  be  paid  by  the  savings  and  loan  associa- 
tions, and  it  is  difficult  to  see  how  the  reduction  in  interest 
which  might  occur  after  a  number  of  years  would  compen- 
sate the  associations  for  the  risk  and  trouble  assumed.  If 
the  Land  Bank  were  cooperative  and  there  were  a  need  or 
desire  for  centralization,  then  of  course  there  would  be  noth- 
ing which  the  associations  should  not  do  to  create  a  system. 


240  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

subject  to  60  days'  call  ?    The  explanation  is  that  withdrawals 
are  discouraged  by  forfeiture  of  entrance  and  transfer  fees, 
the  shares  of  borrowers  are  pledged  to  the  association,  and 
the  business  generally  is  so  arranged  that  the  monthly  pay- 
ments* of  borrowers  suffice   to   meet   dividends,   the   normal 
amount  of  withdrawals  and  the  matured  value  of  shares.    But 
the  chief  reason,  far  above  all  others,  is  that  the  association  is 
cooperative,  members  lend  their  own  money  among  them- 
selves and  with  a  true  cooperative  spirit  accord  easy  terms 
because  of  that  spirit  and  of  the  mutual  confidence  and  trust 
which  prevail  in  the  association.    In  this  way  an  association, 
beginning  with  an  issue  of  50  shares  with  monthly  dues  of  $10, 
will  soon  have  $1,000  which  it  can  lend  safely  until  the  end 
of  the  series,  and  so  on.    If  the  issue  of  new  shares  is  suffi- 
cient to  give  it  a  steady  and  dependable  inflow  of  capital,  it 
will  be  able  to  lengthen  the  period  of  the  loans.    Loans  of 
ten  years  are  frequently  granted,  but  they  are  always  repay- 
able on  the  monthly  instalment  plan.     An  association  ob- 
taining its  fimds  from  withdrawable  shares  cannot,  of  course, 
invest  all  its  assets  in  long-term  loans ;  there  is  a  limit  both 
to  amount  and  to  time  which  it  would  be  dangerous  to  over- 
step.   The  Ohio  savings  and  loan  associations  have  invested 
$11,147,733  in  farm  mortgages.     This  is  less  than  one-sev- 
enth of  their  total  assets,  and  it  has  proved  entirely  safe, 
although  some  of  the  mortgages  run  for  16  years.    Neverthe- 
less it  would  be  advisable  to  exercise  caution  in  extending  this 
practice.     Long-term  loans  prevent  quick  turnovers  of  cap- 
ital, and  thus  are  not  as  profitable  as  short-term  loans  and 
tend  to  reduce  the  size  of  dividends.    The  Ohio  associations 
dealing  with  farmers  have  been  compelled  to  change  their 
highly  profitable   instalment   regulations    and   allow  semi- 
annual payments  and  even  payments  in  lump  at  the  end  of 
the  term. 

There  is  no  reason  why  savings  and  loan  associations  in 
other  states  should  not  follow  the  methods  adopted  in  Ohio, 
admit  some  farmers  to  membership,  and  grant  long-term 
loans  to  a  limited  extent.  This  would  not  only  open  up  a 
new  source  of  loans  for  agriculture  but  also  would  strengthen 


PEINCIPLES  OP  LAND  CEEDIT  241 

the  associations  by  increasing  their  assets.  It  is  doubtful, 
however,  -whether  any  large  degree  of  success  will  attend 
the  efforts  being  made  to  form  associations  composed  exclus- 
ively of  farmers.  In  agricultural  regions  there  are  not  many 
salaried  or  wage-earning  persons.  Contrary  to  the  case  in  the 
cities,  the  rural  residents  are  more  willing  and  able  to  bor- 
row than  to  set  aside  savings  at  interest  or  for  dividends. 
Farmers,  even  tenants,  are  in  business  on  their  ovro  account, 
and  if  they  are  industrious  and  intelligent,  have  immediate 
use  of  their  own  for  all  their  money  and  are  not  able  to  make 
payments  at  short  regular  intervals.  Consequently  the  con- 
ditions essential  to  the  success  of  a  building  and  loan  associa- 
tion do  not  exist  in  the  country.  Farmers  cannot  afford  to 
tie  up  their  money  for  a  long  term  in  the  mortgages  of 
neighbors.  The  prime  object  of  the  reorganization  of  rural 
finance  in  the  United  States  is  to  create  a  system  whereby 
the  farmers  may  utilize  their  savings  as  circulatory  and  work- 
ing capital  and  obtain  from  the  general  public  aU  the  other 
funds  needed  for  the  equipment,  improvement  and  acquisi- 
tion of  land.  If  farmers  and  their  neighboTs  were  to  invest 
their  disposable  funds  in  real-estate  mortgages,  they  would, 
be  subject  to  the  necessity  of  borrowing  all  the  more  heavily 
for  raising  and  marketing  their  crops  and  live  stock. 

Building  and  loan  associations  deal  in  cooperative  credit 
only  in  a  restricted  sense,  since  they  do  not  require  members 
to  obligate  themselves  in  any  way  for  borrowers.  They  are 
formed  for  collective  saving — quite  a  different  thing  from  co- 
operative credit — and  for  investing  the  accumulated  savings 
by  preference  in  mortgages  of  home-builders.  Such  an  associa- 
tion does  not  borrow  nor  does  it  pledge  the  collective  liability 
-of  members  for  the  latter  purpose,  which  is  essentially  secon- 
dary to  its  savings  feature.  The  only  state  contemplating  the 
possibility  is  New  York,  which  by  its  law  as  amended  in  1914 
allows  members  to  impose  unlimited  liability  on  their  associa- 
tion in  favor  of  the  Land  Bank  in  consideration  of  money  or 
bonds  received.  It  is  not  probable  that  the  investing  and  sav- 
ing members  of  the  New  York  associations  will  avail  them- 
selves of  this  right  to  subject  any  considerable  portion  of  the 


243  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

$65,000,000  of  assets  securing  their  savings  to  an  unlimited 
liability  for  raising  money  with  which  to  grant  new  loans  to 
persons  who  may  not  yet  be  members.  Associated  persons 
are  careful  when  they  have  only  their  own  savings  to  invest 
and  are  inclined  to  become  careless  when  they  invest  money 
coming  from  the  outside.  Facile  credit  is  thus  cooperation's 
greatest  danger,  because  it  creates  corresponding  liabilities 
which  must  be  met  eventually,  no  matter  how  accommodating 
the  creditor  may  be  or  how  remote  the  day.  The  soundness 
and  prosperity  of  the  building  and  loan  associations  in  the 
United  States  are  due  to  the  fact  that  expenditures  are  re- 
stricted statutorily  to  a  small  percentage  of  receipts,  and  offi- 
cers are  forbidden  under  penalty  from  involving  an  associa- 
tion in  any  outside  liabilities  except  a  temporary  one  of  a 
limited  amount  to  relieve  stringencies.  The  New  York  laws 
contained  the  same  wise  regulations  until  the  amendment 
authorized  the  directors  to  convert  into  cash  the  mortgages 
taken  to  secure  savings  of  members  and  to  guarantee  bonds  of 
the  Land  Bank. 

The  only  cooperative  association  in  which  collective  liabil- 
ity is  practicable  for  long-term  real-estate  credit  is  an  associa- 
tion composed  entirely  of  borrowers.  Such  is  the  landschaft, 
a  distiactively  rural  association,  and  in  every  country  in 
which  the  landschaft  has  been  introduced  it  has  proved  its 
superiority  for  getting  long-time  loans  for  farmers  at  low 
interest  rates  and  on  easy  terms.  Since  the  debentures  of  a 
landschaft  are  unrecallable,  the  holders  can  never  touch  the 
principal  until  the  landschaft  itself  declares  it  to  be  due. 
Until  then  the  landschaft  is  obligated  to  repay  only  the  semi- 
annual interest  on  the  debentures;  consequently  the  issue  of 
debentures  does  not  involve  the  landschaft  in  an  outside  lia- 
bility, as  is  provided  now  by  the  New  York  law  for  savings 
and  loan  associations.  It  would  seem  better  to  establish  tried 
institutions  of  this  sort  in  the  United  States  than  to  change 
the  building  and  loan  associations,  distinctively  urban  insti- 
tutions, which,  as  they  are  now  statutorily  governed  and  con- 
servatively managed  in  the  cities  and  towns  throughout  the 
country,  afford  the  best  examples  of  cooperative  finance  in  the 


PEINCIPLES  OP  LAND  CREDIT  343: 

•world.  Moreover,  it  would  be  better  to  establish  landschafts 
than  one  large  central  land-credit  bank  or  a  plurality  of  such 
banks.  No  private  joint-stock  banks  in  Europe  have  been 
able  to  grant  much  long-time  credit  to  farmers.  Many  of 
them  grant  three-  and  five-year  mortgages  and  a  few  grant 
instalment  mortgages  of  ten  years,  but  they  do  not  serve 
farmers  to  as  great  an  extent  as  trust  companies,  mortgage- 
bond'  companies  and  savings  and  state  banks  in  the  United 
States.  The  laws  of  the  states,  however,  shoidd  be  so  amended 
as  to  restrict  bond  issues  and  assure  close  ofiBcial  supervision 
for  the  purpose  of  giving  more  protection  to  the  investing 
public.  A  study  of  the  origin  and  purpose  of  the  creation  of 
the  public  or  semi-public  land-credit  institutions,  central  or 
local,  which  exist  ia  a  few  European  countries,  shows  that 
there  are  no  exigencies  calling  for  the  establishment  of  such 
institutions  in  the  United  States. 

The  landschafts  may  be  either  private  or  semi-public.  The 
latter  are  those  in  which  ofiBcials  appointed  or  approved  by 
the  state  are  placed  in  the  administration  to  serve  as  impar- 
tial intermediaries  between  borrowers  and  bondholders.  In 
no  case  is  a  landschaft  aided  or  guaranteed  by  the  state,  nor 
does  it  require  a  monopoly,  although  it  is  well  to  give  it  a 
restricted  and  exclusive  territory.  It  usually  is  privileged, 
however,  to  the  extent  of  having  special  summary  processes 
against  delinquents.  Only  persons  desiring  to  obtain  credit 
on  unencumbered  farm  lands  may  become  members  of  a  land- 
schaft. Its  object  is  to  execute  debentures  on  the  collec- 
tive liability  of  its  members  to  be  issued  to  them  or  in  their 
behalf  in  exchange  for  their  notes  and  mortgages.  A  land- 
schaft, therefore,  has  no  need  of  a  capital  stock,  savings  or  de- 
posits, nor  does  it  have  to  borrow.  It  is  thus  the  safest  kind 
of  financial  institution  which  can  be  imagined,  because  it 
handles  no  funds  except  those  immediately  placed  in  the  best 
kind  of  mortgages.  The  annuities  collected  from  borrowers 
are  used  every  six  months  for  paying  interest  on  debentures 
and  expenses  and  maintaining  a  reserve,  and  for  redeeming 
debentures  or  making  new  loans. 

The  debentures  of  a  landschaft,  based  as  they  are  upon 


344  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  land  and  the  collective  liability  of  the  borrowing  farm- 
ers, are  almost  as  safe  and  sound  as  the  land  scrip  which  the 
United  States  Government  formerly  issued.  Debentures 
would  soon  become  popular  in  the  United  States  if  the  in- 
struments and  the  landschaft  had  the  same  tax  exemptions 
as  a  savings  bank  or  a  building  and  loan  association;  in  that 
case,  naturally,  they  could  be  issued  and  sold  at  a  low  interest 
rate  and  without  fixed  date  for  their  maturity.  This  would 
bring  cheap  money  to  farmers  and  in  addition  permit  the 
landschaft  to  grant  reducible  loans  repayable  by  annuities 
running  for  30,  40,  50  or  75  year:  or  a  period  desired  by  the 
borrower. 

It  has  been  asserted  that  American  farmers  do  not  want 
long-time  credit.  The  truth  of  this  assertion  can  be  ascer- 
tained only  after  the  facilities  have  been  provided.  Long- 
term  loans  would  enable  tenants  to  become  landowners  by 
paying  their  debts  out  of  the  annual  produce  of  the  soil.  The 
evils  of  tenancy  have  already  made  their  appearance  to  an 
alarming  extent  in  the  United  States.  Long-term  loans 
would  enable  farmers  with  love  of  home  and  pride  of  family 
to  acquire  broad  acres  and  build  substantial  residences  at  an 
expense  to  be  borne  in  part  by  their  sons.  The  most  patriotic 
citizens  in  all  countries  are  freeholders  with  firesides  near  to 
ancestral  graves.  Long-term  loans  would  enable  the  farmers 
to  convert  into  annuity  contracts  the  $3,000,000,000  of  three- 
and  five-year  mortgages  which  now  encumber  their  lands,  and 
thus  save  themselves  from  the  costs  of  repeated  renewals  and 
the  dangers  of  foreclosure.  If  this  stupendous  amount,  com- 
posed in  part  of  debts  running  back  for  many  years,  were 
spread  out  over  the  future,  the  farmers  would  be  able  to  em- 
ploy more  of  their  income  to  the  present  needs  of  agriculture. 


PAET  n.    COOPEEATIVE  CREDIT 


CHAPTER  XX 

COOPBEATION  AND  COOPERATIVE  CEEDIT 

Definition. — Administration. — Objects. — Cooperative  Society  versus 
Partnership  and  Corporation. — ^History  of  Corporations. — Eise  of 
Modem  Cooperation. — English  Trade  Unions. — Beginnings  in 
Germany  and  Prance. — Work  of  Schulze-Delitzseh  for  Trades- 
people and  Workingmen. — ^Raiffeisen 's  Activities  for  Agricultur- 
ists.— ^Luigi  Luzzatti. — ^Advantage  of  Cooperation  for  Farmers. 
— Two  Arrangements  in  Europe. 

CooPERATioiT  is  the  act  of  persons,  voluntarily  tinited,  of 
utilizing  reciprocally  their  own  forces,  resources  or  both  under 
their  mutual  management  to  their  common  profit  or  loss. 
The  partnership,  corporation  or  association  may  be  used  as 
the  form  of  organization  for  carrying  on  the  business  for 
which  they  thus  unite,  but  the  latter  form  is  the  one  most 
frequently  adopted. 

The  administration  of  the  associational  form  of  organiza- 
tion difEers  in  details  among  different  societies  but  never  as 
regards  its  important  features.  In  all  countries  it  comprises 
a  committee  of  control  and  a  committee  of  management,  both 
elected  by  members,  and  supervising  oflScials  elected  ia  the 
same  way  or  appointed  by  outside  authority;  and  these  bodies 
are  separate  and  independent  the  one  from  the  other  and  are 
required  to  keep  records  and  render  reports  of  their  opera- 
tions so  that  their  honesty  and  efficiency  may  be  assured  by 
wise  counterchecks  and  the  light  of  publicity  upon  all  their 
acts.  The  power  of  the  members  is  supreme  but  it  may  be 
exercised  only  at  meetings  regularly  assembled,  at  which  a 
majority  prevails.  A  capital  stock  is  not  essential,  but  if  it 
exists  it  consists  of  subscriptions  of  persons  enrolled  as  mem- 
bers, belongs  to  them  individually  and  not  to  the  association, 

247 


248  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

and  is  subject  to  increase  or  diminishment  by  the  admission 
and  retirement  of  members  and  by  the  payments  and  with- 
drawals of  payments  on  their  subscriptions :  hence  the  amount 
of  the  stock  and  the  number  of  members  are  not  fixed  but 
constantly  fluctuate  above  a  certain  prescribed  minimimi. 

The  subscriptions  are  simple  membership  agreements  con- 
ferring certain  rights  always  revocable  by  the  association  and 
imposing  certain  obligations,  among  which  may  be  that  of 
paying  specified  sums  usually  in  periodical  instalments.  They 
are  not  in  any  sense  shares  of  stock,  and  while  they  may 
determine  the  extent  of  the  members'  liabilities  toward  the 
association  and  its  creditors,  they  do  not  indicate  their  voting 
strength.  No  matter  how  large  the  sum  or  sums  for  which 
a  member  may  have  subscribed,  the  number  of  his  votes  is 
so  limited  as  to  prevent  the  control,  management  or  super- 
vision of  the  association  from  being  dominated  by  the  mere 
power  of  money.  A  cooperative  society  is  an  association  of 
individuals  as  distinguished  from  a  combination  of  capital, 
and  the  rights  of  members  therein  cannot  be  transferred  nor 
entrusted  to  proxies  except  by  the  society's  grace,  and  then 
only  to  other  members;  consequently,  a  member  cannot  hide 
his  identity  or  escape  responsibility  with  the  ease  possible  to 
a  shareholder  in  a  corporation.  A  cooperative  is  legally  and 
morally  bound  by  the  acts  of  his  society,  while  the  liability 
for  its  financial  obligations  which  he  assumes  collectively 
with  his  fellow  members  may  involve  severally  as  well  as 
jointly  without  limit  his  entire  individual  assets  and  credit. 

A  cooperative  society  may  and  in  some  circumstances  must 
of  necessity  deal  with  outsiders,  but  its  benefits  and  advan- 
tages are  all  confined  to  members.  In  this  respect  it  differs 
from  a  partnership  or  a  corporation  the  associates  in  which 
are  beneficiaries  of  its  economic  action  only  as'  they  are  a 
part  of  its  general  clientage.  Again,  a  partnership  is  com- 
posed of  a  few  designated  persons  who  individually  own  its 
assets  much  in  the  same  way  that  cooperatives  own  those  of 
their  society,  but  in  each  of  whom  its  entire  power  and  lia- 
bility are  lodged  as  regards  third  parties.  A  corporation  has 
assets  and  franchises  owned  and  managed  by  the  body  itself 


COQPEEATION  AND   COOPEEATIVB   CEEDIT      S49 

as  a  legal  entity  apart  from  its  shareholders.  While  these 
shareholders,  like  members  of  a  cooperative  society,  may  vote 
for  officials,  they  vote  by  shares  and  not  as  individual  persons, 
and  have  no  title  ia  the  properties  of  the  corporation,  and 
are  not  responsible  for  any  of  its  acts.  Thus  in  spirit,  or- 
ganization and  administration  there  are  vital  points  of  dif- 
ference between  corporations,  partnerships  and  cooperative 
societies. 

As  regards  objects,  however,  they  are  all  alike.  They  may 
engage  in  the  same  kinds  of  business,  and  when  so  engaged 
they  aim  to  make  profits,  effect  economies,  and  further  the 
interests  of  the  associates.  The  devotion  of  the  cooperative 
society  to  the  interest  of  its  associates,  however,  is  the  most 
pronounced,  since  it  imposes  qualifications  for  participating 
membership,  grants  this  only  when  it  may  be  of  advantage  to 
itself  and  persons  admitted,  excludes  the  public  wherever  it 
is  possible  to  do  so,  and  conducts  its  operations  as  on  a  com- 
mon account  for  the  mutual  benefit  of  members  alone.  There 
is  nothing  intrinsically  altruistic  or  benevolent  in  cooperation. 
The  notion  that  it  is  based  on  charity  to  be  mutually  bestowed 
and  shared  or  to  be  spoon-fed  by  the  government  or  philan- 
thropists to  feeble  folk  is  a  mistake  of  wide  exposition.  Coop- 
eratives cannot  give  or  receive  alms  without  weakening  their 
fiber.  They  may  or  may  not  be  inspired  by  brotherly  love, 
but  the  cement  which  holds  them  together  is  the  desire  or  need 
to  gain  or  save.  Cooperation  is  strictly  business-like  in  its- 
purposes  and  methods,  and  it  has  achieved  its  greatest  and 
most  enduring  successes  among  persons  capable  of  relying 
upon  themselves  and  strong  enough  to  refuse  tenders  of  out- 
side aid. 

With  the  exception  of  bodies  endowed  by  the  government 
with  special  and  sometimes  monopolistic  privileges,  the  coop- 
erative society,  partnership  and  corporation  are  the  only  forms 
of  organization  for  business,  if  corporations  public  and  pri- 
vate, with  or  without  stock,  be  considered  as  one  class.  Of 
these  three  forms  the  cooperative  society  has  proved  to  be 
the  best  for  consumers,  for  groups  of  small  mercantile  and 
industrial  producers,  and  for  all  farmers  rich  or  poor.    The 


250  ETJEAL   CREDITS 

extensive  powers  lodged  in  the  associates  of  a  partnership 
make  this  form  of  organization  not  only  impracticable  but 
dangerous  for  the  large  number  of  persons  who  usually  consti- 
tute a  cooperative  society.  A  corporation  may  have  a  numer- 
ous membership,  but  it  is  difficult  to  maintain  the  spirit  of 
mutuality  within  it,  while,  since  its  very  organic  existence 
depends  upon  the  possession  of  wealth,  it  is  necessarily  capi- 
talistic and  its  tendency  is  to  subordinate  aU  other  objects  to 
the  increase  of  its  assets,  and  this  is  so  whether  its  adminis- 
tration be  cooperative  or  otherwise.  Moreover,  a  corporation 
cannot  combine  workers  or  consumers  without  funds  in  hand 
for  united  action  in  behalf  of  themselves  as  readily  as  an  asso- 
ciation can  fulfill  this  object  for  respective  members,  because 
their  future  gains  and  savings  are  an  unknown  quantity  and 
a  value  which  cannot  be  computed  in  advance  and  used  as  a 
basis  for  a  fixed  capital. 

A  cooperative  society  is  free  from  these  objections.  Its 
capital  stock,  if  it  has  one,  not  being  fixed  like  that  of  a  cor- 
poration, by  its  variability  allows  members  to  pay  up  their 
shares  as  they  cam  or  save  the  money  and  to  withdraw  the 
money  as  they  have  other  uses  for  it.  This  fiuctuation  can 
cause  no  trouble  under  normal  conditions,  because  the  only 
need  which  a  cooperative  society  has  for  money  is  for  carry- 
ing on  the  business  of  members,  and  the  capital  requirements 
of  this  business  grow  correspondingly  less  as  its  proportions 
become  smaller  with  the  retirement  of  members.  So  the 
cooperative  society  is  preeminently  adapted  for  the  classes 
mentioned  when  they  wish  to  utilize  their  own  funds  and 
resources  for  their  own  purposes:  but  for  farmers — it  will 
be  seen  later  on — cooperation  cannot  develop  its  full  useful- 
ness without  combination;  there  must  be  cooperation  among 
the  cooperative  societies  as  well  as  among  their  individual 
members  so  as  to  create  a  system,  and  at  the  base  of  this 
system  should  be  the  credit  society. 

The  cooperative  association  is  the  oldest  form  of  organiza- 
tion for  economic  action.  It  has  been  so  long  in  general  use 
that  all  European  races  have  records  showing  that  it  preceded 
their  political  organization.    The  earliest  type  was  the  group 


COOPEKATION   AND   COOPEEATIVB    CEEDIT    251 

of  kinsfolk  or  neighbors  loosely  bound  together  for  their 
common  good  or  for  helping  one  another  in  some  enterprise 
too  big  to  be  undertaken  by  individuals  alone.  The  corpora- 
tion, the  other  form  of  combiaation  which  permits  of  a  union 
of  numbers,  is  of  recent  origin  when  compared  with  the  coop- 
erative society.  It  became  possible  only  after  circulating 
wealth  had  accumulated  and  there  were  persons  with  sur- 
pluses larger  than  their  actual  needs  which  they  were  willing 
to  entrust  in  ventures  beyond  their  immediate  control,  and 
after  there  had  arisen  a  numerous  class  of  consumers  exist- 
ing apart  from  the  producers  and  able  to  buy  what  the  latter 
could  supply. 

The  corporation,  however,  was  the  first  to  receive  legal 
recognition.  At  first  corporations  were  not  governed  by  gen- 
eral laws  but  each  was  created  by  a  special  act,  and  they  were 
generally  composed  of  persons  of  great  influence  with  the 
government,  invested  by  royal  decree  with  a  monopoly  or 
privileges  of  an  exclusive  character  obtained  and  used  by  the 
grantees  for  some  large  project  or  grand  enterprise.  The 
nobility  were  invariably  represented  among  these  grantees, 
for  in  those  days  the  nobility  were  all-powerful  in  the  state 
and  owned  most  of  the  large  fortunes  by  reason  of  their  ex- 
tensive landed  estates,  and  from  them  alone  could  the  desired 
franchises  and  the  needed  capital  be  procured. 

Thus  the  corporation  started  with  aristocratic  influence  and 
was  generally  intimately  identified  with  the  government,  since 
its  noble  shareholders  had  votes  in  the  parliament  or  the 
cabinet  of  the  King.  The  Hudson's  Bay  Company  which  was 
incorporated  with  Prince  Eupert  as  the  head  and  granted 
vast  stretches  of  territory  and  a  trading  monopoly  in  Canada, 
the  grant  of  Pennsylvania  to  William  Penn,  John  Law's 
Company  of  the  West  which  acquired  Louisiana,  and  the 
enormous  companies  which  were  granted  trading  monopolies 
by  France  and  England  over  the  South  Seas  and  the  East 
Indies  are  typical  examples  of  the  mode  in  which  big  busi- 
ness was  launched  in  those  days  by  corporations  and .  royal 
favors.  And  when  trade  and  commerce  assumed  tremendous 
jjroportions  in  consequence  of  the  development  of  modern 


352  EUEAL   CREDITS 

transportation  facilities  which  opened  up  new  worlds  for 
exploitation,  and  when  industrial  and  mercantile  pursuits  took 
on  their  present  importance  and  infinite  variety  as  a  result 
of  the  discoveries  and  inventions  of  science,  the  corporation, 
which  yet  remains  the  only  private  means  for  amassing  capi- 
tal, became  the  dominating  factor  in  business  life.  The  laws 
which  were  enacted  to  give  corporations  a  statutory  form 
were  drafted  also  to  encourage  their  growth,  for  the  European 
nations  were  struggling  for  supremacy  and  each  realized  the 
very  plain  truth  that  no  undertaking  requiring  large  funds 
to  be  used  in  distant  lands  or  employed  for  indefinite  periods 
can  be  attempted  except  through  the  corporate  form  of  or- 
ganization, with  a  capital  stock  divided  into  shares  of  a  size 
suitable  to  the  average  run  of  investors  and  involving  no 
personal  responsibility  for  the  management  or  liability  for  its 
debts. 

The  corporations  throve  and  multiplied  under  this  favor- 
ing action  of  the  governments.  They  found  strong  advocates 
in  the  first  school  of  political  economists,  whose  studies  re- 
lated mainly  to  the  accumulation  of  wealth,  and  their  powers 
were  enlarged  by  lawyers  and  judges.  The  eloquence  of 
Daniel  Webster  in  the  Dartmouth  College  case,  for  example, 
induced  the  Supreme  Court  of  the  United  States  to  decide 
that  the  grant  of  a  franchise  by  the  state  to  a  corporation  was 
as  inviolable  as  a  contract  between  private  individuals;  in 
other  words,  that  while  a  nation  may  annul  a  treaty  with 
another  nation,  it  cannot  divest  a  citizen  of  privileges  once 
bestowed.  With  the  rise  and  expansion  of  incorporated  busi- 
ness, household  industries  and  handicrafts  disappeared  and 
other  momentous  changes  began  to  manifest  themselves  in 
Europe.  The  landed  estates  the  titles  to  which  had  descended 
from  the  feudal  system  were  being  broken  up ;  personal  prop- 
erty was  becoming  as  important  as  real  estate  and  was  yield- 
ing larger  fortunes;  the  nobles  were  giving  way  to  the  aris- 
tocracy of  wealth,  and  the  barons  of  commerce  and  industry 
were  taking  their  place  as  the  masters  of  the  liberated  serfs 
who  were  swarming  in  the  cities.  Social  and  economic  con- 
ditions were  undergoing  an  entire  readjustment,  and  iucor- 


COdPEEATION   AND    COOPEEATIVE    CEEDIT    253 

porated  business  was  most  powerful  and  active  wherever  the 
rich  were  getting  richer  and  the  poor  were  getting  poorer. 

But  reaction  set  in  almost  as  soon  as  trouble  manifested 
itself,  and  this  politically  intrenched  system,  which  consid- 
ered only  the  accumulation  of  wealth  and  paid  slight  atten- 
tion to  the  cruel  inequalities  of  its  distribution,  soon  became 
a  violently  agitated  subject  of  reform.  A  new  school  of  po- 
litical economists  arose  to  advance  the  rights  of  man  against 
the  rights  of  property,  and  various  theories  were  broached  or 
put  to  practice  with  the  object  of  rescuing  the  -poor  from  an 
industrial  slavery  which  threatened  to  be  more  oppressive  than 
that  suffered  under  feudalism.  Visionaries  planned  Utopias 
elaborated  on  the  form  of  the  association  of  old  pastoral  days, 
and  their  dreams  materialized  in  communistic  settlements 
into  which  workmen  might  retire  and  sever  all  connection 
with  the  outside  world.  Some  of  the  communities  located  in 
the  wilds  of  America  still  exist.  The  more  practical  men 
sought  to  reform  society  from  within,  to  break  up  the  inti- 
mate relation  between  the  government  and  vested  private  in- 
terests, to  abolish  monopoly  and  special  privilege,  and  then 
to  assure  justice  and  equality  either  by  giving  freedom  of 
action  under  the  law  to  all  or  by  placing  all  business  in  the 
hands  of  the  government.  Their  ideas  as  to  these  alterations 
were  confused  with  a  perplexing  similarity  at  the  start,  but 
eventually  the  line  between  them  became  clearly  drawn  aud 
socialism  sprang  up  on  one  side  and  modern  cooperation  on 
the  other. 

A  bitter  antagonism  arose  between  the  protagonists  of 
these  two  theories  when  an  active  propaganda  was  launched 
for  their  ideas  about  the  middle  of  the  last  century.  Today, 
however,  there  are  socialists  who  believe  in  cooperation  and 
cooperatives  who  believe  in  socialism.  The  reason  for  this  is 
that,  industrially  considered,  both  have  an  aim  in  common, 
which  is  to  give  to  the  producer  an  equitable  portion  of  the 
wealth  he  creates.  But  socialism  when  it  adopts  cooperation 
adopts  it  as  one  of  many  means  to  its  end,  while  a  coopera- 
tive who  is  a  socialist  is  such  just  as  he  may  be,  a  German  or 
an  American,  a  Christian  or  a  Jew.    Barring  this  identity  in 


354  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

respect  to  aim,  the  two  forces  are  irreconcilably  different  the 
one  from  the  other.  Socialism  is  political  and  often  militant. 
It  stands  for  government  ownership  of  all  sources  and  dis- 
tributing agencies  of  wealth  and  even,  ia  its  most  radical 
form,  for  the  abolition  of  private  title  to  property;  and  it 
strives  to  coerce  everyone  into  joining  its  ranks  whether  he 
would  or  no.  But  cooperation  has  no  politics,  at  least  outside 
of  the  trade  unions.  It  rests  upon  self-help,  opposes  state 
intervention,  and  demands  simple  equality  and  freedom  of 
action  under  the  law.  It  wants  the  adherence  of  no  one  but 
him  who  is  willing  to  join,  and  it  insists  inexorably  upon  the 
individual  ownership  of  property  and  the  right  of  all  to  hold 
absolutely  as  their  own  whatever  they  can  honestly  earn  and 
acquire.  Hence,  the  harmony  maintained  at  present  must 
dissolve  in  antagonism  again  when  the  campaign  recently  in- 
augurated for  cooperation  reaches  a  more  advanced  stage  and 
its  principles  become  better  understood. 

The  advent  of  modern  cooperation  was  with  the  English 
trade  unions,  which  were  formed  in  the  early  part  of  the  nine- 
teenth century  for  increasing  wages  and  supporting  members 
during  strikes  and  lockouts.  These  trade  unions,  however, 
were  mutual  benevolent  organizations  which  strove  to  attain 
their  objects  through  the  exercise  of  political  power.  They 
were  followed  by  a  number  of  associations  with  a  purely 
economic  purpose  created  within  the  next  decade  under  the 
leadership  of  Eobert  Owen,  the  rich  reformer  who  mixed 
cooperation  with  free  love  and  other  radical  ideas.  The 
first  appearance  of  cooperative  credit  was  in  the  United  States, 
with  the  foundation  of  the  Oxford  Provident  Building  Asso- 
ciation at  Frankford,  a  suburb  of  Philadelphia,  on  July  3, 
1831.  The  first  agricultural  cooperative  society  in  England 
was  that  formed  at  Assington,  in  1838,  by  15  farmers  who 
put  up  $15  apiece,  borrowed  $3,000  more  on  their  collective 
liability  from  a  man  named  Gordon,  rented  75  acres  of  his 
estate,  allotted  this  land  among  themselves,  and  cultivated  it 
without  hiring  labor  or  paying  salaries.  In  1844  was  founded 
the  Equitable  Pioneers  of  Eochedale,  with  a  capital  of  $140 
contributed  by  28  flannel  weavers,  mechanics  and  shoemakers 


COOPEEATION   AND   COOPEEATIVE    CEEDIT    255 

for  buying  supplies  to  sell  at  wholesale  prices  to  members. 
At  the  time  this  society  was  being  formed,  Victor  A.  Huber 
was  propagating  the  idea  of  association  for  workmen  and 
tradespeople  in  Germany,  but  long  before  he  grasped  the 
standard,  tentative  efforts  toward  cooperation  had  been  made 
among  various  classes  in  Germany  and  other  countries  on  the 
Continent. 

In  1800  German  tradespeople  essayed  the  cooperative  pur- 
chase of  raw  material,  and  the  establishment  of  cooperative 
dyeing-houses  and  sale  centers.  In  1821  farmers  in  the 
Rhine  province  collectively  bought  and  operated  a  windmill 
for  grinding  grain,  and  there  seem  to  have  been  during  that 
period  numerous  mill  associations  on  the  Hunsruek,  besides 
communal  bakeries  in  several  districts  along  the  Ehine.  In 
the  sixteenth  century  there  were  drainage  unions  in  Holland 
and  during  the  Middle  Ages  similar  unions  of  the  peasants 
in  Italy  and  Spain,  while  in  Prance  there  were  peasants'  asso- 
ciations for  productive  purposes  in  the  thirteenth  and  twelfth 
centuries.  These  instances  are  only  a  few  of  the  many  which 
might  be  cited.  Indeed,  almost  as  far  back  as  history  can 
be  traced,  associated  action  appears  to  have  been  a  common 
occurrence  among  farmers,  tradespeople  and  small  producers 
in  all  European  nations,  and  in  Eussia,  China  and  Japan; 
for  in  the  days  when  circulating  money  was  scarce  and  the 
mechanism  of  exchange  had  not  yet  been  perfected,  bartered 
commodities  frequently  were  gathered  and  disposed  of  col- 
lectively in  traffic,  labor  was  exchanged  for  labor,  and  all  this 
sometimes  led  to  cooperation  in  some  form  or  other. 

Thus,  unlike  the  corporation  system,  the  cooperative  asso- 
ciation arose  amid  humble  surroundings  away  from  the  foster- 
ing care  of  government  and  unaided  by  special  privilege  or 
even  by  recognition  in  law.  Its  first  essays  were  feeble  and 
sporadic.  Nevertheless  it  had  already  made  substantial  prog- 
ress when  students,  philanthropists  and  statesmen  at  last  re- 
alized that  it  could  be  developed  into  a  great  social  and  eco- 
nomic force  for  protecting  farmers  and  the  plain  people  not 
only  against  the  oppressive  aggression  of  capitalism  but  also 
from  the  dangers  of  radical  socialism.     The  movement  in 


256  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

"this  direction  on  the  European  continent  began  in  Germany 
about  the  middle  of  the  last  century.  At  that  time  the  Ger- 
man Confederation  was  undergoing  the  disturbances  attend- 
ant on  the  change  from  the  old  to  the  new  order  of  things. 
The  cities  were  crowded  with  workmen  out  of  employment  or 
forced  to  accept  whatever  pittance  was  tendered  them  as  a 
daily  wage.  The  small  trading  classes  were  succumbing  in 
"the  unequal  struggle  with  organized  capital  and  large-scale 
industry.  The  peasants,  freedmen  or  serfs  in  many  districts 
were  too  ignorant  and  poverty-stricken  to  do  good  farming, 
■while  profits  in  agriculture  had  sunk  nearly  to  the  vanishing 
•point  because  of  the  development  of  ocean  steamship  naviga- 
tion which  began  regular  service  in  1838  and  was  now  seri- 
ously affecting  the  prices  of  grain  and  meat  in  the  principal 
markets  by  importations  from  the  United  States. 

In  the  midst  of  these  troublous  times  the  poor  were  re- 
duced to  want  and  misery  by  a  drought  which  lasted  from 
1846  to  1848.  The  rich  distributed  free  bread,  flour,  pota- 
ioes,  seed  and  breeding  cattle  to  relieve  suffering  in  places 
"where  it  was  most  intense,  or  opened  public  balieries,  stores 
and  loan  offices  for  selling  these  supplies  to  the  needy  cheaply 
and  on  easy  terms. 

Two  men,  Herman  Sehulze-Delitzsch  and  Frederick  Wil- 
liam Henry  Eaiffeisen,  both  of  whom  subsequently  attained 
imdying  fame,  were  foremost  among  the  organizers  of  this 
Telief  work  in  Germany.  Sehulze-Delitzsch  was  quick  to 
comprehend  the  limitations  to  the  usefulness  of  charity,  and 
within  a  couple  of  years  he  inaugurated  the  movement  which 
he  promoted  to  the  end  of  his  life  for  inducing  tradespeople 
and  workmen  to  form  associations  for  mutual  self-help.  He 
was  familiar  with  the  history  of  cooperation,  his  investigations 
of  this  subject  having  been  inspired  by  the  teachings  of  Hu- 
ber,  and  before  formulating  his  plans  he  made  a  close  study 
of  existing  associations,  especially  of  those  of  industrial  work- 
ers for  buying  raw  materials  in  France  and  the  Eochedale  and 
other  laborers'  wholesale  societies  in  England.  Whether  he 
loiew  of  the  Frankford  building  and  loan  association  cannot 
"be  said  certainly,  but  he  probably  did  know  of  it,  because  he 


COOPEEATION    AND    COOPBEATIVE    CEEDIT    257 

was  a  follower  of  Henry  Charles  Carey,  the  American  econo- 
mist, who  lived  in  Philadelphia,  had  read  all  his  works,  and 
most  likely  had  corresponded  with  him. 

The  conclusion  reached  by  Schulze-Delitzsch  from  his  in- 
vestigations and  studies  was  that  the  first  need  of  coopera- 
tives was  money  and  that  consequently  the  basic  unit  of  their 
organization  should  be  a  credit  society  financed  by  their  own 
thrift  or  savings  and  by  funds  borrowed  on  their  collective 
liability.  He  believed  that  after  they  had  familiarized  them- 
selves with  simple  banking  methods  and  the  uses  of  credit 
and  gained  a  standing  in  financial  circles,  they  would  be  in  a 
position  to  apply  cooperation  to  all  other  kinds  of  business. 
Schulze,  however,  did  not  start  the  first  society  organized 
along  these  lines.  That  honor  belongs  to  Dr.  Bernhardi  and 
a  tailor  named  Buerman,  who  reduced  the  theory  to  practice 
at  Eilenburg,  Germany,  on  October  1,  1850,  while  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  was  still  working  on  the  details.  Schulze-Delitzsch 
did  not  make  a  practical  application  of  his  principles  until 
the  summer  of  1852,  when  he  reorganized  an  association 
which  he  had  founded  in  1850  at  Delitzsch  to  conform  with 
that  in  Eilenburg.  But  this  does  not  bedim  the  glory  which 
is  his  of  having  evolved  in  logical  order  the  theory  of  this  new 
credit  created  out  of  the  capitalized  character  of  groups  of 
honest  and  industrious  persons,  which  has  proved  to  be  as 
sound  a  security  as  can  be  obtained  regardless  of  how  weak 
the  individual  \mits  may  be.  Schulze-Delitzsch's  literary  and 
oratorical  talents,  which  enabled  him  to  expound  the  theory 
in  a  clear  and  forceful  manner,  and  his  enthusiasm  and  effec- 
tive activities  for  the  cause  soon  made  him  the  recognized 
leader  in  the  movement  and  brought  him  followers  from  all 
sides.  As  time  went  on  his  ideas  expanded  and  developed  a 
new  science  of  economics  which  brought  him  into  an  open 
conflict  on  the  one  side  with  the  autocratic  Bismarck  and  on 
the  other  with  the  brilliant  socialist  Ferdinand  Lassalle;  for 
to  Schulze-Delitzsch  mutual  self-help  meant  cooperation  based 
on  individualism  and  the  inviolability  of  the  right  to  private 
property  veithout  assistance  or  interference  by  the  government. 
He  denounced  state  aid  as  vehemently  as  he  inveighed  against 


358  EUEAL   CREDITS 

charity,  and  also,  while  he  maintained  that  cooperatives  should 
consider  themselves  as  parts  of  the  whole  for  their  common 
good,  he  urged  that  each  should  preserve  his  integral  identity 
and  utilize  the  advantages  of  association  first  for  his  own 
benefit  and  then  for  that  of  his  fellow  members.  The  success 
of  cooperation  as  propounded  by  Schulze-Delitzsch  is  due  to 
the  fact  that  it  does  not  violate  human  instincts  nor  raise  to 
a  morbid  degree  of  sentimentality  the  quality  of  brotherly 
love. 

The  organization  and  business  methods  of  Schulze-De- 
litzsch's  credit  and  savings  societies,  or  rather  people's  banks, 
are  better  adapted  to  mercantile  and  industrial  classes  with 
small  stores  or  establishments  of  their  own  than  to  workmen 
or  farmers.  Indeed,  he  confined  his  activities  largely  to 
tradespeople  in  urban  centers  and  encouraged  workmen  to 
join  as  members  only  when  they  wished  to  save  or  obtain 
loans  to  become  producers  on  their  own  account.  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  never  gave  any  particular  attention  to  the  agricul- 
tural classes.  The  betterment  of  the  farmers  in  Germany 
was  brought  about  by  EaifEeisen.  In  the  bleak  and  barren 
district  of  the  Westerwald  in  which  Eaiffeisen  worked  out 
the  true  principles  of  agricultural  credit,  the  peasants  were 
reduced  to  such  penury  that  during  the  famine  of  1846  and 
1847  their  usual  meal  was  sauerkraut  and  chicory  brew,  and, 
as  Henry  W.  Wolff  says,  this  half-starved  population,  "iU- 
clad,  Hi-housed,  ill-brought  up,  by  hard  labor  eked  out  barely 
enough  to  keep  body  and  soul  together  with  the  support  of 
the  scanty  produce  of  their  little  patches  of  rye,  of  buckwheat 
or  potatoes  and  the  milk  and  flesh  of  some  half -famished  cat- 
tle, for  the  most  part  hopelessly  pledged  to  the  Jews." 

In  the  beginning  Eaiffeisen's  sole  object  was  to  relieve  the 
distress  of  these  miserable  creatures  and  rescue  them  from 
their  usurious  oppressors,  and  for  this  purpose  he  resorted  to 
the  use  of  pure  charity  without  any  notion  of  cooperation. 
His  appeals  for  funds  and  assistance  were  liberally  responded 
to  because  as  mayor  of  one  of  the  towns  and  always  an  active 
religious  and  social  worker,  he  had  a  high  ofiBcial  and  personal 
standing  in  the  district.     But  Eaiffeisen,  like  Schulze-De- 


COOPEEATION    AND    COOPERATIVE    CEEDIT    359 

litzsch,  also  found  that  charity  was  producing  no  lasting  bene- 
ficial effect,  and  he  transformed  the  benevolent  associations 
which  he  had  organized  with  the  aid  of  his  rich  friends  into 
loan  ofiSees  for  according  credit  to  peasants,  finally  admitting 
these  borrowers  to  full  membership  and  responsibility,  while 
striving  at  the  same  time  to  retain  the  rich  members  in  the 
associations.  This  change,  however,  was  not  made  until  many 
years  after  he  had  formed  his  first  society  at  Flammersfeld,  in 
December,  1849.  That  the  suggestion  came  from  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  is  shown  by  the  following  extract  from  a  letter 
written  by  Eaiffeisen  on  July  9,  1864,  relative  to  the  forma- 
tion of  a  credit  society  to  replace  a  charitable  association 
which  he  had  established  at  Heddesdorf : 

I  was  loath  to  give  up  the  idea  that  cooperative  societies 
should  be  based  on  charity  without  thought  of  self  or  pelf.  I 
maintained  my  original  idea  in  a  letter  to  the  weU-known 
organizer,  Mr.  Schulze-Dehtzsch,  an  efficient  worker  in  econ- 
omies, but  experience  compels  me  frankly  to  admit  that  such 
societies  must  consist  only  of  the  persons  who  personally  need 
their  help  and  thus  have  an  interest  in  keeping  them  going. 

With  the  object  of  preventing  a  repetition  of  the  unfortunate 
experiences  at  Flammersfeld,  I  have  resolved  to  allow  the  society 
here  at  Heddesdorf  to  be  dissolved,  and  then  to  organize  another 
society  at  an  early  date  upon  the  new  principles  mentioned 
above.  Already  I  have  made  most  satisfactory  progress,  prac- 
tically upon  the  model  of  the  Sehulze-Delitzsch  associations. 
However,  since  the  latter  are  formed  mainly  for  cities  and 
towns,  I  have  made  certain  changes  in  the  by-laws  to  adapt 
them  to  local  conditions.  So  far  I  have  obtained  the  signatures 
of  about  300  reliable  and  industrious  citizens  of  the  district, 
etc. 

Eaiffeisen  was  not  the  sole  originator  of  the  type  of 
credit  society  which  bears  his  name.  The  first  society  of 
this  kind  was  organized  at  Anhausen  in  1862,  probably  by  his 
brother-in-law,  the  Eeverend  W.  Eenckhoff,  and  it  was  not 
until  April  25,  1869,  that  Eaiffeisen  adopted  all  its  features, 
although  he  had  assisted  at  the  formation  of  the  Anhausen 
society.    Thus  17  years  intervened  between  the  dates  at  which 


260  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

Sehulze-Delitzsch  and  Eaiffeisen  brought  their  respective  ideas 
to  maturity.  While  the  former  was  a  national  celebrity  early 
in  life,  the  work  of  Eaiffeisen  did  not  attain  renown  beyond 
its  local  environment  until  he  had  reached  middle  age.  In- 
deed it  did  not  achieve  results  of  large  proportions  until  after 
his  death,  but  the  posthumous  fame  of  Eaiffeisen  now  out- 
shines the  glory  of  his  more  successful  rival,  because  coopera- 
tive credit  is  spreading  more  rapidly  among  the  agricultural 
classes  for  whom  he  worked  than  among  the  tradespeople  and 
laboring  men  who  were  the  peculiar  care  of  Schulze-Delitzseh. 

With  the  names  of  these  two  men  must  be  coupled  that  of 
Luigi  Luzzatti  of  Italy,  who  originated  in  1866  a  modified 
type  of  the  Schulze-Delitzseh  bank  which  now  is  more  exten- 
sively used  than  its  model.  The  theories  evolved  by  these 
three  men  must  be  studied  carefully  in  order  to  arrive  at  a 
full  understanding  of  the  principles  of  cooperative  credit,  but 
the  fact  must  not  be  overlooked  that  these  three  types  of  socie- 
ties exist  only  in  their  native  countries,  and  not  always  in 
their  pristine  purity  even  there,  because  laws  subsequently 
enacted  in  nearly  every  European  coimtry,  now  require  co- 
operative societies  to  be  formed  and  managed  and  their  busi- 
ness to  be  conducted  according  to  statutory  regulations.  The 
agricultural  mutual  banks  of  France  also  deserve  to  be  studied 
because  they  are  a  conspicuous  example  of  state  aid  bestowed 
as  judiciously  as  governmental  assistance  can  be  bestowed  and 
the  best  example  of  the  peculiar  arrangement  known  as  "syn- 
dicalism." The  associations  in  all  other  countries  are  adapta- 
tions of  these  types.  Most  of  them  are  mainly  agricultural, 
and  wherever  they  are  numerous  and  active  they  have  been 
formed  into  systems  by  grouping  local  associations  under 
regional  associations  and  linking  up  the  latter  with  central 
institutions. 

Indeed,  cooperative  credit  for  agricidture  has  never  been 
introduced  in  any  country  without  keeping  constantly  in  view 
the  aim  of  ultimately  creating  a  system.  Scattered  agricul- 
tural credit  associations  operating  independently  of  one  an- 
other are  foredoomed  to  failure  or  at  least  to  an  uncertain  and 
temporary  existence.    An  agricultural  cooperative  credit  asso- 


COOPEEATION   AND    COOPEEATIVE    CEEDIT    261 

ciation  which  does  not  lead  to  the  formation  of  other  asso- 
ciations in  its  locality  will  quickly  disappear,  and  especially  is 
this  true  if  lending  and  saving  be  its  only  facilities.  Farmers 
as  a  rule  do  not  have  any  money  to  place  at  interest  or  to 
allow  to  lie  idle  in  banks  because  they  can  always  find  imme- 
diate employment  on  their  own  farms  for  whatever  money 
they  may  make.  Hence  a  cooperative  association  which 
serves  merely  as  a  safe  place  for  deposit  and  loans  at  current 
interest  rates  offers  no  attractions  to  farmers,  for  they  can 
easily  obtain  that  service  elsewhere  without  assuming  any  of 
the  trouble  and  responsibility  of  the  management  or  subject- 
ing themselves  to  collective  liability  for  defaults  of  borrow- 
ing members. 

The  only  difference  which  can  exist  between  the  interest 
rates  of  a  cooperative  credit  society  and  an  ordinary  bank 
comes  from  the  economies  effected  in  the  former  by  not  pay- 
ing large  salaries  or  sharing  profits  with  outside  stockholders 
or  third  parties.  The  compensation  of  a  cooperative  for 
the  use  of  his  money  or  credit,  like  that  of  any  other  money 
lender  must  be  regulated  strictly  by  market  conditions.  The 
cooperative  credit  associations  in  Europe  which  do  not  demon- 
strate this  practical  truth  are  those  assisted  by  the  state  or 
charity,  and  since  their  benefactors  naturally  demand  par- 
ticipation in  the  control  or  management  to  assure  a  proper 
use  of  their  aid,  the  spirit  of  mutuality  and  independence 
is  weakened  by  this  outside  interference.  In  the  few  coun- 
tries where  the  associations  depend  on  charity  or  state  aid, 
the  members  lack  private  initiative,  are  inclined  to  look  upon 
the  donations  and  appropriations  as  gratuities  not  to  be  re- 
paid even  by  thanks,  and  are  in  constant  need  of  new  bene- 
factions to  keep  them  together. 

What  then  induces  farmers  to  form  a  cooperative  credit 
society?  The  reason  is  that  besides  the  reduction  of  interest 
rates  on  loans  resulting  from  the  saving  of  expenses,  it  offers 
other  advantages  of  a  more  important  character  by  acting  as 
the  business  head  or  financial  center  of  all  activities  in  the 
neighborhood.  It  either  makes  collective  purchases  or  sales 
for  members,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies. 


262  EUKAL   CREDITS 

and  thus  enables  them  to  obtain  supplies  at  wholesale  prices 
and  to  dispose  of  their  products  without  paying  commissions 
to  middlemen;  or  else,  as  ia  the  case  of  French  syndicalism, 
the  credit  association  or  its  members  form  other  associations 
connected  with  it  for  these  purposes. 

It  is  a  disputed  question  in  Europe  as  to  which  of  these 
arrangements  is  the  better  for  farmers.  The  general  belief, 
however,  is  that  at  the  beginning,  when  the  credit  associa- 
tions are  weak  and  few  in  number,  they  should  combine  the 
purchasing  of  supplies  and  the  distributing  of  products  with 
their  banking  business,  and  that  after  cooperation  has  become 
firmly  established  in  a  locality,  the  credit  association  should 
leave  trading  and  industrial  pursuits  to  other  cooperative 
associations  specially  organized  therefor  but  so  grouped 
around  and  identified  with  it  that  it  may  attend  to  their 
financial  transactions.  By  the  adherence  of  these  associa- 
tional  members  the  importance  of  the  credit  society  is  in- 
creased, and  it  is  able  to  keep  its  funds  in  constant  circula- 
tion and  to  pay  to  depositors  and  to  shareholders,  if  it  has 
any,  the  highest  interest  rates  realized  by  money  within  the 
area  of  its  operations. 

It  is  thus  as  necessary  to  study  the  systems  of  cooperation 
in  the  various  countries,  with  their  federations  and  unions 
which  act  as  propagating  and  organizing  bodies,  as  to  study 
the  associations  composing  them.  The  central  and  regional 
institutions  are  either  joint-stock  corporations  or  associa- 
tions with  variable  capital,  whose  shares  are  held  by  the 
associations  next  in  rank  under  them,  and  whose  affairs  are 
conducted  by  managers  elected  by  these  shareholders.  The 
majority  of  the  local  associations  for  credit  as  well  as  for  in- 
dustrial and  mercantile  purposes  have  a  variable  capital,  but 
many  of  the  credit  societies, — and  these  are  the  base  of  all, — 
have  no  share  capital  but  operate  with  deposits  and  loans  at- 
tracted and  obtained  by  the  collective  liability,  usually  unlim- 
ited, of  members. 


CHAPTEE   XXI 

THE    SCHTILZE-DELITZSCH    PEOPLE'S    BANKS 

Early  Life  of  Schulze. — Founding  of  Associations  for  Working- 
men. — ^Political  Career. — ^Later  Loan  Associations. — Spread  of 
Movement. — Attitude  of  Prussian  Government. — ^Death  and 
Eeputation  of  Schulze. — Henry  CJharles  Carey. — Claude-Frederic 
Bastiat. — Scotch  Banks  and  "Character"  Credit. — ^Plan  of 
Sehuize  People's  Bank. — Operation  and  Organization  of  a 
Bank. — Objection  to  Centralization. 

Heemait  Schulze  was  bom  on  August  29,  1808,  at 
Delitzsch,  a  small  town  in  Prussian  Saxony,  whose  name  he 
subsequently  added  to  bis  own.  His  ancestors  had  been 
mayors  and  judges  for  generations,  and  he  was  the  oldest  of 
ten  children  of  a  distinguished  magistrate.  He  graduated 
from  the  University  of  Leipsig,  went  through  the  law  school 
of  the  University  at  Halle,  was  admitted  to  the  bar  at  23 
years  of  age,  and  after  passing  the  competitive  examinations 
was  placed  on  the  eligible  list  for  appointment  to  a  position 
in  the  judiciary  department  of  the  Prussian  Government. 
He  was  assigned  to  duty  in  the  court  of  Naumburg  and  soon 
afterwards  in  the  chamber  of  justice  at.  Berlin.  He  quitted 
Berlin  in  1841  to  take  a  similar  post  at  Delitzsch,  the  easy 
responsibilities  of  which  enabled  him  to  make  a  number  of 
trips  to  foreign  lands,  including  France,  the  Tyrol,  Italy, 
Norway,  Sweden,  and,  some  say,  England.  His  inclination 
towards  political  life  led  him  to  study  economics  and  the 
science  of  government,  and  there  is  reason  to  believe  that 
during  his  travels  he  familiarized  himself  with  the  Fjench 
artisans'  associations  for  buying  raw  materials,  the  English 
laborers'  wholesale  buying  associations,  and  trade  unions  and 
the  Scotch  methods  of  banking,  because  cooperation,  currency 

263 


364  RTIEAL   CEEDITS 

reform  and  the  diffusion  of  credit  were  at  that  period  topics 
of  lively  discussion  throughout  the  Germanic  Confederation. 

Upon  his  return  to  his  native  town  Schulze  engaged  in. 
social  uplift  work.  He  organized  an  athletic  and  glee  club, 
of  which  he  became  president,  and  actively  interested  him- 
self in  the  social  and  political  life  of  hi^  community.  In 
the  lean  years  of  1846  and  1857  he  assembled  a  relief  com- 
mittee, collected  funds  and  rented  a  mill  for  buying  and 
grinding  flour  and  a  bakery  for  making  and  distributing 
bread  to  the  destitute  free  or  at  a  low  price.  After  the 
famine  he  formed  an  insurance  society  for  the  poor  against 
sickness  and  death,  and  during  the  next  few  years  various 
other  societies  were  formed  in  rapid  succession,  by  his  direct 
assistance  or  as  a  result  of  his  teachings,  which  included  a 
traders'  bank  at  Elbing  in  1848;  an  association  for  buying 
raw  materials  for  carpenters  and  shoemakers  at  Delitzsch  in 
1849;  a  loan  office  at  Cuestrin  in  1849  and  another  at 
Delitzsch  in  1850;  a  food-supply  association  and  a  credit 
society  at  Eilenburg  in  1850;  a  food-supply  association  at 
Delitzsch;  an  association  for  buying  leather  for  shoemakers 
at  Bitterf eld,  and  an  association  for  buying  cloth  for  tailors 
at  Delitzsch  in  1853. 

Schulze  was  elected  a  deputy  from  Delitzsch  to  the  Na- 
tional Assembly  at  Berlin  in  1848,  and  thereupon  changed  his 
name  to  Schulze-Delitzsch  to  distinguish  himself  from  his 
many  relatives  and  another  Schulze  in  the  legislature. 
Schulze-Delitzsch  was  a  progressive  in  politics.  He  partici- 
pated in  the  debates  and  boldly  opposed  the  attempts  of  the 
Government  to  establish  a  military  dynasty  and  intervene  in 
all  human  affairs.  He  was  appointed  chairman  of  the  legis- 
lative committee  formed  to  investigate  the  labor  question 
and  his  recommendations  did  not  meet  with  the  approval  of 
the  Government.  He  also  voted  against  increasing  the  war 
taxes  and  was  indicted  on  this  account  for  treason  in  1849 
along  .with  the  majority  of  the  Assembly.  Schulze-Delitzsch 
conducted  the  defense.  All  the  defendants  were  acquitted 
by  a  jury  in  Berlin,  whose  verdict  was  inspired  not  only  by 
the  rights  of  the  case  but  by  the  indignation  aroused  by  the 


THE  SCHULZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    365 

invasion  of  the  Assembly  by  an  armed  force  xmder  orders 
irom  tbe  Minister  of  War.  Sehulze-Delitzscb's  victory  made 
Mm  a  popular  hero  but  it  inflamed '  the  animosity  of  the 
Government,  which  had  looked  upon  him  with  suspicion  and 
distrust  ever  since  he  began  to  organize  associations  for  poor 
■workmen  and  tradespeople. 

A  reorganization  of  the  judiciary  gave  the  Government 
an  opportunity  to  satisfy  its  grudge  against  Schulze-Delitzsch 
by  relegating  him  to  Wreschen,  a  small  Polish  village  in  the 
Duchy  of  Posen  on  the  Russian  frontier.  He  was  assigned 
"to  this  post  practically  as  an  exile,  but  he  applied  himself 
"with  assiduity  to  the  discharge  of  his  duties,  and  added  to  his 
iame  by  settling  satisfactorily  an  important  and  difficult  land- 
credit  ease.  His  request  for  a  furlough  to  recuperate  his 
health  and  attend  to  his  personal  affairs  at  home  was  denied. 
He  left  Wreschen,  nevertheless,  and  when  the  Government 
■docked  his  salary  and  was  preparing  to  show  its  displeasure 
^at  his  unauthorized  absence  in  a  more  emphatic  manner,  he 
"tendered  his  resignation  from  the  judiciary  service  and  in 
1851  returned  to  Delitzsch  to  live. 

Schulze-Delitzsch  found  that  during  his  exile  his  associa- 
"tions  had  been  neglected  and  that  the  society  for  loans  at 
Delitzsch  was  doing  nothing.  With  the  exception  of  the 
Eilenburg  association  all  the  associations  were  charitable,  and 
although  they  received  deposits  and  borrowed  on  the  collective 
liability  of  members,  they  were  managed  and  financed  entirely 
"by  the  rich  and  weU-to-do  members.  The  EUenburg  associa- 
■fcion,  however,  was  a  pure  cooperative  credit  society  based  on 
self-help  and  managed  by  the  borrowing  members.  It  began 
with  180  members  and  in  1853  had  586  members  to  whom  it 
had  made  717  loans  averaging  300  thalers  ($142)  each.  A 
few  years  later,  however,  it  disbanded  because  of  a  misun- 
derstanding between  Dr.  Bernhardi  and  the  tailor  Buerman 
who,  as  stated  in  the  preceding  chapter,  were  its  founders. 

The  loan  association  of  Schulze-Delitzsch,  at  Delitzsch,  was 
composed  of  members  of  his  athletic  and  glee  club,  and  it 
was  organized  in  1850  as  the  direct  consequence  of  a  refusal 
of  the  savings  bank  in  that  town  to  extend  financial  help 


266  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

to  the  various  associations  which  had  been  organized  in 
that  locality.  The  first  step  which  Schulze-Delitzsch  took 
upon  his  return  from  Wreschen  to  put  the  association  on  its 
feet  was  to  request  the  municipal  authorities  to  advance  it 
200  thalers  for  working  funds.  This  request  was  refused, 
although  Schulze-Delitzsch  offered  to  let  them  designate  two 
judges  and  one  alderman,  one  of  them  to  be  chairman  of 
the  board  of  directors,  to  serve  as  a  committee  with  one  vote 
in  the  administration  of  the  association.  Schulze-Delitzsch 
thereupon  resolved  to  reorganize  the  Delitzsch  association 
and  base  it  entirely  upon  the  principle  of  self-help  which  had 
proved  so  successful  in  the  Eilenburg  society,  and  this  was 
done  in  the  summer  of  1852.  The  membership  immediately 
rose  from  30  to  150  and  the  society  was  soon  able  to  obtain 
all  the  money  sufficient  for  its  needs  at  five  per  cent.  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  never  again  asked  for  public  aid  or  charity;  his 
early  appeals  he  ever  remembered  with  regret,  and  he  excused 
them  by  referring  to  the  overwhelming  emergencies  of  the 
times. 

Gradually  the  two  credit  associations  at  EUenburg  and 
Delitzsch  were  followed  by  others  in  the  province  of  Posen 
and  the  kingdom  of  Saxony.  The  next  was  formed  in  1853 
at  Zoerbig  near  Delitzsch,  and  others  were  formed  ia  1854 
at  Eisleben  and  Peine,  and  in  1855  in  Cella,  Meissen,  Bitter- 
feld  and  Sangenhausen.  By  1859  there  was  in  existence  183 
people's  banks  with  18,676  members,  and  it  was  decided  to 
hold  a  convention  to  discuss  ways  and  means  of  giving  a 
proper  direction  to  the  movement  and  extending  it  through- 
out the  country.  Schulze-Delitzsch  planned  to  hold  the  con- 
vention at  Dresden,  but  this  was  forbidden  by  the  King  of 
Saxony  who  suspected  some  political  purpose  arising  from  the 
widespread  discontent  which  then  prevailed  among  tradespeo- 
ple and  workmen,  and  the  convention  was  transferred  to 
Weimar.  Twenty-nine  associations  were  represented  by  38 
delegates.  A  permanent  organization  was  formed  which  sub- 
sequently became  known  as  the  General  Federation.  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  was  elected  president,  and  was  voted  a  salary  to 
consist  of  two  per  cent  of  the  net  profits  of  all  the  associations. 


THE  SCHULZE-DBLITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    267 

s 

on  the  understanding  that  he  should  engage  in  no  other  busi- 
ness and  should  devote  all  his  time  and  ability  to  the  Federa- 
tion. He  accepted  this  position  with  the  title  of  "salaried 
agent  and  counselor  of  the  mutual  cooperative  associations  of 
Germany,"  and  from  1860  until  his  death  he  devoted  himself 
exclusively  to  its  duties. 

About  this  time  Schulze-Delitzseh  was  elected  to  the 
Chamber  of  Deputies  again  and  thenceforth  became  one  of 
the  most  conspicuous  figures  in  public  life,  always  fighting 
for  cooperation  and  the  rights  of  the  plain  people.  On  the 
one  hand,  he  continued  to  denounce  the  militarist  tendency 
of  the  Government,  and  his  opposition  was  so  formidable  that 
King  William  I  of  Prussia  is  alleged  to  have  said,  "We  shall 
see  in  the  end  which  of  the  two  shall  triumph,  Mr.  Schulze 
or  myself."  On  the  other  hand,  Sehulze-Delitzsch  was  the 
foe  most  hated  and  feared  by  the  socialists.  Lassalle  made 
him  and  his  doctrines  the  principal  objects  of  attack.  After 
the  untimely  death  of  this  brilliant  theorist  in  1864,  the 
gage  of  battle  was  taken  up  by  other  violent  protagonists,  but 
they  were  unable  to  check  the  continuous  increase  in  the  num- 
ber of  Schulze-Delitzsch's  societies  and  followers.  In  the  face 
of  Bismarck's  opposition  Schulze-Delitzseh  had  practically 
made  a  political  party  for  himself  through  his  talents  for 
writing,  speaking  and  organizing.  In  1864  admirers  pre- 
sented him  with  about  $37,500  raised  by  public  subscription. 
He  accepted  this  gift  on  the  condition  that  after  his  death 
the  revenues  of  the  fund  should  be  used  to  help  worthy  men 
engaged  in  social  welfare  work.  The  refusal  of  the  French 
authorities  to  allow  an  international  congress  on  cooperation 
to  be  held  at  the  Universal  Exposition  at  Paris  in  1867  added 
to  the  strength  of  the  movement  he  had  inaugurated  on  the 
Continent,  and  he  was  idealized  at  home  and  abroad  as  the 
greatest  advocate  of  democracy  and  friend  of  the  lower  classes 
in  Europe. 

By  1861  there  were  in  the  German  Confederation  364 
people's  banks  with  48,760  members,  besides  many  cooperative 
societies  for  other  purposes  than  credit.  They  were  operating 
practically  outside  of  the  law  since  no  legislation  relating  to 


268  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

cooperation  had  yet  been  enacted.  They  frequently  met  with 
interference  by  the  public  authorities,  who  claimed  the  right 
to  approve  their  articles  of  agreement  or  by-laws  and  to  forbid 
operations  without  such  approval.  At  the  annual  convention 
in  1861  it  was  resolved  to  secure  proper  legislation.  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  drafted  a  bill  for  this  purpose  in  1862  which  be- 
came the  cooperative  law  of  Prussia  in  1867  and  of  various 
other  German  states  in  1871  and  1873.  For  this  the  Univer- 
sity of  Heidelberg  conferred  upon  him  the  degree  of  doctor 
of  laws,  because  he  "was  the  man  who  created  for  associa- 
tions the  right  form  and  new  laws,  and  thereby  improved  and 
enlarged  the  science  of  jurisprudence."  But  he  did  not  live 
long  enough  to  witness  the  completion  of  his  legislative  work 
with  the  enactment  of  the  German  law  of  May  1,  1889,  which 
still  remains  in  force  with  a  slight  amendment  made  in  1896. 
Schulze-Delitzseh  died  at  Potsdam  on  April  29,  1883.  In 
that  year  there  were  no  less  than  1,910  Schulze-Delitzseh 
societies  with  466,575  members  in  Germany,  and  hundreds 
of  others  of  a  pure  or  modified  form  of  his  type  in  other 
European  countries.  In  1891  his  statue  in  bronze,  the  cost 
of  which  was  paid  by  international  subscription,  was  erected 
in  the  central  square  of  his  native  village,  and  a  few  years 
later  a  monument  costing  more  than  $70,000  was  raised  to 
his  memory  in  Berlin.  But  long  before  his  death  his  leader- 
ship had  been  disputed  and  the  cooperative  movement  in 
Germany  divided  into  warring  factions.  His  writings,  begin- 
ning with  his  first  book  in  1853,  however,  were  read  by  all 
as  text  books,  and  were  the  most  efEective  literature  for 
spreading  information  on  the  -theory  and  practice  of  co- 
operation on  the  European  continent  during  the  latter  part 
of  the  nineteenth  century.  The  authors  who  directed  the 
trend  of  Schulze-Delitzsch's  thoughts  on  politics  and  econom- 
ics were  the  American  Henry  Charles  Carey,  and  the  French- 
man Claude-Frederic  Bastiat,  who  was  himself  a  follower  of 
Carey.  Indeed  Schulze-Delitzseh  was  called  by  Lassalle  the 
Bastiat  of  Germany,  while  by  Benjamin  Eampal,  the  French 
philanthropist  who  willed  a  large  fortune  to  the  poor,  he  was 
looked  upon  as  Carey's  chief  disciple. 


THE  SCHULZB-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    269 

-  Carey,  the  son  of  an  Irish  bookseller,  lived  in  Philadel- 
phia from  his  birth  in  1793  to  his  death  in  1879.  In 
America  he  is  known  as  the  first  protectionist.  In  Europe 
he  is  famed  as  one  of  the  first  political  economists  who  con- 
sidered that  the  rights  of  man  are  more  important  than 
the  rights  of  property.  Carey  believed  that  every  individual 
was  entitled  to  a  fair  share  of  the  wealth  accumulated  in 
society  according  to  his  capacity  to  acquire  it.  He  attributed 
the  concentration  of  wealth  under  the  control  of  those  who 
did  not  create  it  to  an  unnecessary  multiplicity  of  inter- 
mediaries or  middlemen,  and  to  eliminate  them  he  advocated 
associations  among  producers  and  consumers  so  as  to  retain 
the  control  of  trade  and  commerce  withia  their  own  hands. 

Bastiat  was  born  at  Mugron,  in  the  canton  of  Landes,  in 
1801,  and  died  at  Eome  in  1850.  He  was  one  of  the  most 
famous  of  the  French  political  economists  of  his  day.  He 
pointed  out  that  in  isolation  a  man's  needs  are  greater  than 
his  power  to  supply  them,  while  in  combined  action  with 
associates  they  are  considerably  less.  Hence,  wealth  tends 
to  increase  in  a  social  state,  and  its  increase  enables  each 
succeeding  generation  to  raise  a  more  numerous  progeny. 
Division  of  labor  and  exchange  necessarily  arise  out  of  this 
continuous  increase  of  wealth  and  population.  Bastiat  did 
not  object  to  this  condition.  He  wished  to  readjust  society 
so  as  to  reconcile  the  interests  of  the  different  classes  in  it, 
and  to  prevent  one  man's  profit  from  being  another  man's 
loss.  He  believed  in  private  property  and  denounced  those 
among  the  socialists  who  wished  to  turn  it  over  to  the  govern- 
ment, and  the  levelers  who  wished  to  redistribute  it  share 
and  share  alike  among  the  people.  He  declared  that  prop- 
erty was  the  fruit  of  labor  and  its  stability  the  greatest  in- 
ducement to  labor.  He  felt  that  every  individual  would  ac- 
quire his  just  share  if  he  had  the  right  and  opportunity  to 
work.  Malthus'  fear  of  excessive  population  did  not  alarm 
Bastiat.  In  his  opinion  the  means  of  subsistence  were  prac- 
tically inexhaustible,  and  the  increasing  numbers  of  people, 
if  their  efforts  could  be  combined,  would  make  supplies  plenti- 
ful, cheapen  the  cost  of  living,  do  away  with  the  harsh  neces- 


270  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

sity  of  contimial  work,  and  afford  leisure  for  recreation  and 
for  social  and  intelleeftial  improvement. 

The  salary  or  wage  appeared  to  Bastiat  the  best  way  to 
judge  the  worth  of  laborers.  He  encouraged  them  neverthe- 
less to  form  societies  for  savings  and  for  mutual  assistance  in 
ease  of  sickness  or  want,  and  finally  he  came  out  unreservedly 
in  favor  of  progressive  association,  that  is,  the  gradual  bring- 
ing together  of  capital,  labor  and  talent  for  the  good  of  hu- 
manity. The  sole  condition  he  imposed  was  that  associations 
of  this  nature  should  be  voluntary  and  that  their  expenses 
should  not  be  borne  by  those  who  refused  to  enter  them.  Had 
Bastiat  not  died  at  a  comparatively  early  age,  he  would  prob- 
ably have  been  a  great  writer  on  cooperation,  for  in  his  last 
book  he  asserted  that  society  is  nothing  more  than  association, 
and  that  the  failure  of  its  parts  to  act  in  harmony  "clearly 
shows  that  it  is  still  in  its  infancy." 

According  to  Mr.  A.  de  Malarc,  who  visited  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  in  an  official  capacity  in  1868  and  published  an 
account  of  his  interview  in  a  report  submitted  to  the  French 
Chamber  of  Deputies  in  1894  in  which  he  asserts,  "herein 
it  is  Schulze-Delitzsch  who  speaks  through  my  voice,"  the 
great  German  cooperative  drew  his  ideas  regarding  the  dif- 
fusion of  popular  credit  from  the  banks  of  Scotland  and 
adopted  for  his  people's  banks  their  methods  of  extending 
credit,  particularly  those  of  cash  credits  and  the  use  of  the 
indorsement  of  neighbors  instead  of  mortgage  or  collateral 
as  security  for  short-time  loans. 

The  Scotch  banks  almost  from  their  beginning  have  ex- 
tended their  services  to  small  customers.  In  1695  the  Bank  of 
Scotland  was  chartered  with  a  monopoly  and  unlimited  powers 
of  issue  as  to  both  amount  and  denominations.  This  monopoly 
was  taken  away  when  the  Eoyal  Bank  was  incorporated  in 
1727.  Trade  and  commerce  proved  to  be  too  light  to  keep  the 
resources  and  notes  of  both  these  banks  in  circulation,  and  in 
1729  the  Royal  Bank  began  to  send  agents  around  the  coun- 
try. They  visited  the  fairs  and  the  villages  on  market  days. 
They  taught  the  shopkeeper  and  the  crofter  that  the  use  of 
money  and  the  backing  of  the  bank  could  be  bought  at  an 


THE  SCHULZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    271 

agreed  price  as  any  other  commodity.  They  also  taught  the 
young  men  how  their  reputations  for  honesty  and  industry, 
if  known  to  neighbors,  could  be  capitalized  for  an  amount 
sufficient  to  set  them  up  in  business. 

If  the  agents  found  a  worthy  man  who  needed  a  little 
money  for  some  economy  or  productive  purpose,  they  would 
give  him  a  dravring  account  at  the  bank  up  to  a  specified 
amount  upon  the  indorsement  of  a  couple  of  friends,  with 
the  understanding  that  he  would  deposit  his  savings  or  gains 
with  the  bank.  The  agents  came  promptly  at  appointed  times 
to  coUect  these  sums,  and  interest  was  allowed  and  charged 
on  the  daUy  balances.  Thus  the  bank  kept  watch  over  the 
use  of  the  money  that  was  drawn  and  closed  the  account 
if  it  became  inactive  or  threatened  a  loss.  Hence  there  was 
every  reason  for  a  person,  when  once  he  had  entered  into  rela- 
tions with  the  bank,  to  be  industrious  and  accumulate  as 
large  a  balance  in  his  favor  as  possible.  This  practice  is 
called  Scotch  or  cash  credit,  and  the  manner  in  which  it  is 
diffused  through  agents  and  local  branches  in  Scotland  has 
brought  banking  to  the  very  doors  of  the  people,  implanted 
a  spirit  of  thrift,  honesty  and  enterprise  in  them,  and  enables 
them  by  close  connections  with  the  banks  to  obtain  expert 
advice  as  well  as  financial  assistance  in  the  conduct  of  their 
affairs. 

The  credit  accorded  in  Scotland  on  the  good  faith  of 
the  borrower  and  his  reputation  for  industry,  sobriety 
and  thrift,  when  guaranteed  by  two  or  three  friends, 
Schulze-Delitzsch  designated  as  "character"  credit.  Since  no 
person  or  institution  in  his  locality  ordinarily  would  take  such 
a  risk,  the  only  alternative  was  the  usurers.  He- knew,  how- 
ever, that  the  average  man  is  honest  and  able  to  pay  debts 
incurred  for  his  own  business  purposes  if  given  a  reasonable 
chance,  and  finally  he  hit  upon  the  plan  of  having  the  bor- 
rowers assume  their  own  risks,  of  combining  them  in  groups 
to  make  the  individual  risk  as  light  as  possible,  and  then  of 
diffusing  this  form  of  credit  by  inducing  the  trading  and 
working  classes  to  form  little  banks,  organized  and  managed 
like  the  cooperative  associations  then  existing  in  England,  for 


273  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

collecting  and  investing  their  own  savings  and  for  raising 
money  from  outside  sources  for  members  in  case  of  need  on 
their  joint  and  several  liability.  His  plan  as  outlined  by 
himself  for  his  first  bank  in  1850  was  as  follows: 

Individually  you  find  difficulty  in  obtaining  the  necessary 
money  to  buy  the  raw  materials  which  you  require  in  your 
"work.  So  then  organize  an  association  by  a  regular  contract 
of  agreement  upon  the  collective  liability  of  such  of  you  whose 
habits  of  industry  and  correct  living  are  known  in  the  neigh- 
horhood. 

Do  not  forget  that  your  object  should  be  to  borrow  to 
produce,  that  is,  to  give  a  plus  value  to  the  money  you  have 
borrowed  so  that  you  may  be  able  to  pay  it  back  with  interest 
and  some  profit.  But  never  borrow  for  consumption,  as  is 
frequently  the  ease  with  wage-earners  who  render  themselves 
liable  to  default.  Let  your  union  be  strictly  a  credit  associa- 
tion among  producers,  and  small  producers  if  possible. 

Then  you  should  gradually  form  a  capital  stock  or  guarantee 
fund  to  be  composed  of  payments  on  shares  of  $30  or  less  and 
entrance  fees.  Each  member  should  pay  his  dues  monthly  and 
thus  little  by  little  pay  up  the  amount  of  his  share.  After  the 
venture  has  proved  successful  you  might  increase  the  fund  by 
adding  to  it  a  part  of  the  profits  of  the  association. 

Each  of  you  should  deposit  his  savings  with  the  association, 
which  should  pay  interest  on  them,  but  naturally  somewhat 
lower  than  the  interest  on  loans.  These  deposits  wiU  form  at 
the  same  time  an  additional  guaranty  fimd  and  a  working 
capital.  Tour  association  will  then  be  a  savings  bank,  but  one 
that  will  be  managed  by  the  depositors  through  officers  of  their 
own  selection. 

If  your  association  should  need  more  money,  you  should  go 
to  some  lender  and  offer  to  him  your  joint  and  several  liability 
as  security  therefor.  Each  member  should  be  responsible  to 
the  full  extent  of  his  individual  property  and  resources  for  all 
operations.  "All  for  one  and  each  for  all"  shoidd  be  your 
motto.  This  unlimited  liability  appears  to  me  indispensable 
at  the  beginning,  in  order  to  put  all  on  guard  in  an  association 
composed  of  persons  not  yet  accustomed  to  forethought  and 
financial  matters.  It  will  oblige  each  to  watch  his  associates  as 
well  as  himself.    Later  on,  when  you  have  become  better  trained 


THE  SCHULZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    273 

and  acquainted  with  each  other,  and  lenders  appreciate  your 
credit  value,  you  might  limit  this  responsibility.  But  for  the 
present  it  should  be  unlimited. 

Tour  association  should  be  based  on  personal  credit.  A. 
cooperative  association  of  small  producers  which  can  obtain 
credit  only  upon  real  estate,  or  by  pledging  collateral,  chattels,, 
implements  or  live  stock,  does  not  deserve  credit.  It  would  be 
dangerous  to  extend  credit  to  it.  Tour  own  selves  and  char- 
acters must  create  your  credit,  and  your  collective  liability 
win  require  you  to  choose  your  associates  carefully,  and  to 
insist  that  they  maintain  regular,  sober  and  industrious  habits, 
making  them  worthy  of  credit. 

This  is  a  reason  why  you  should  not  resort  to  public  or 
charitable  sources  for  loans.  This  is  also  why  no  official  of  a 
government  savings  bank,  or  manager  of  a  foundation  formed 
by  donations  of  the  state,  province  or  coromune,  or  grand  lords 
or  rich  persons,  should  be  connected  with  your  association. 
Such  people  are  inclined  or  prompted  to  extend  credit  because 
of  patronage  or  politics,  and  on  considerations  quite  different 
from  your  real  worth  as  producers. 

Away  with  the  complaisant  and  charitable  lender.  Away 
with  the  loan  which  has  the  appearance  of  a  gift,  and  which 
does  not  obligate  the  borrower  to  the  acknowledgment  of  his 
debt  and  bind  him  to  its  prompt  and  positive  repayment.  For 
any  loans  you  may  need,  address  yourselves  to  a  banker,  who 
will  treat  you  as  any  other  applicant,  a  banker  who  selects  his 
customers  without  any  view  of  charity  or  politics,  and  to 
protect  himself  against  possible  loss  assures  himself  that  the 
borrower  is  clever,  capable,  orderly  and  good  for  the  repayment 
of  the  loan. 

Moreover,  have  nothing  to  do  with  the  man  who  would  pro- 
cure you  easy  credit,  a  credit  more  easy  than  that  open  to  other 
producers.  That  man  would  ofier  to  you  a  deadly  gift.  Easy 
credit  is  often  the  cause  of  ruin,  especially  to  the  small  producer 
who  has  not  yet  habits  of  order  and  forethought,  and  who  lives 
from  day  to  day  without  keeping  an  exact  account  of  his  affairs, 
and  knows  nothing  about  the  cost  of  production  or  its  returns. 

What  you  need  is  fair  credit  on  terms  equal  to  those  accorded 
to  any  other  good  industrial  enterprise.  Go  to  a  banker  who 
does  not  depend  on  public  or  charitable  funds  but  who  risks 
his  own  fortune  in  his  business.  Everybody  knows  that  there 
is  no  lack  of  money  during  ordinary  times  at  the  local  banks. 


274  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

What  they  most  need  is  good  borrowers.  Any  one  of  them  will 
supply  you  with  money,  and  it  will  do  more  than  that.  It  will 
help  you  to  rise  from  the  class  of  workers  without  credit  to  the 
class  of  workers  with  credit;  and  you  will  improve  your  well- 
being  every  degree  that  you  rise  in  the  economic  scale  of 
producers. 

Without  doubt  it  will  take  you  longer  to  reach  your  aim 
through  yourselves  and  cooperative  association  than  it  would 
by  resorting  to  government  banks  and  charity.  Yes,  certainly 
it  takes  longer  to  build  credit  up  from  the  bottom  than  to  let 
it  come  down  from  on  high;  and  it  does  not  please  small 
producers  to  say  to  them:  "Only  by  well  regulated  lives  and 
by  proper  rules  of  conduct  imposed  upon  yourselves,  shall  you 
obtain  credit."  Nevertheless,  this  credit,  which  you  do  not 
obtain  from  another  as  a  bounty  or  alms,  is  in  reality  the 
credit  which  you  create  by  elevating  yourselves.  Eesults  may 
be  slower,  but  they  will  be  more  sure,  deep  and  lasting. 

Your  association,  having  thus  opened  the  sources  of  credit, 
will  grant  individual  loans  to  members  out  of  its  disposable 
funds.  The  executive  committee  elected  from  the  members  at 
the  annual  meeting  of  the  shareholders,  may  be  authorized  to 
lend  to  any  member  a  sum  double  the  amount  of  the  value  of 
his  own  property,  and  even  more,  if  guaranteed  by  the  indorse- 
ment of  two  members.  The  loans  should  be  granted  for  three 
months  ordinarily,  and  for  six,  nine  and  twelve  months  or 
more,  in  cases  where  the  committee  shall  deem  it  wise  to  pro- 
long the  time.  It  may  also  refuse  loans  to  a  member  who  can- 
not give  sufficient  security,  defaults  payments,  or  gets  into 
legal  troubles. 

Very  few  changes  have  been  made  in  this  original  plan. 
Schulze-Delitzsch  worked  among  laborers  and  tradespeople 
in  the  villages  and  cities,  and  today  the  people's  banks  are 
mostly  urban,  although  many  have  a  large  agricultural  busi- 
ness and  membership.  But  whether  in  town  or  country  they 
spurn  the  thought  of  state  aid  and  charity,  public  or  private, 
and  depend  upon  the  industry  and  economy  of  members  to 
raise  the  funds  they  need.  While  serving  mainly  the  middle 
classes  and  sometimes  poor  people,  they  have  no  use  for 
idlers,  profligates  or  incapable  persons.  They  are  not  re- 
formatory houses  or  benevolent  institutions.     They  admit 


THE  SCHULZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    275 

only  those  who  have  orderly  habits,  good  reputations  and  suf- 
ficient cash  in  hand  to  prove  that  they  are  worthy  applicants. 
All  members  must  hold  themselves  equally  liable  for  any  obli- 
gations iacurred  by  their  bank.  Unlimited  liability  is  still 
recommended  for  a  small  society  at  the  beginning,  but  this 
■was  never  an  essential  point.  Schulze-Delitzseh  and  his 
immediate  successor  warmly  advocated  it,  but  the  national 
convention  of  his  societies  in  Germany  in  1894  passed  a  reso- 
lution favorable  to  limited  liability,  and  in  1896  declared  that 
no  distinction  should  henceforth  be  made  in  the  matter. 

The  objects  of  a  people's  bank  are  to  encourage  saving 
among  members  and  to  extend  or  find  credit  for  them.  As  a 
first  step  towards  accomplishing  these  objects  Schulze- 
Delitzseh  provided  that  each  member  should  subscribe  for  a 
share.  The  average  value  of  shares  for  an  unlimited- 
liability  bank  is  $75,  and  for  a  limited-liability  bank, 
$125.  The  member  may  pay  it  up  in  lump  or  by 
instalments  as  low  as  12  or  25  cents  a  week.  In 
addition  he  must  pay  an  entrance  fee.  Schultze-Delitzsch 
set  this  at  $2.60,  but  in  well  established  societies  it  is  often 
three  or  four  times  this  amount,  so  as  to  equalize  the  rights 
and  obligations  of  the  old  and  new  members.  It  may  be 
paid  by  monthly  payments,  but  can  never  be  withdrawn  by 
the  member  as  it  becomes  the  property  of  the  bank  until 
dissolution. 

The  amounts  paid  on  the  shares  belong  to  the  members 
and  may  be  withdrawn  upon  retirement,  usually  on  three 
months'  notice.  They  form  the  capital  of  the  bank,  which 
increases  and  decreases  with  the  number  of  members  and  their 
payments  and  withdrawals.  By  reason  of  this  the  capital  of 
a  people's  bank  differs  entirely  from  the  capital  of  a  cor- 
poration, which  is  fixed  by  its  charter  and  when  once  paid  in 
by  the  shareholders  becomes  its  exclusive  property.  Schulze- 
Delitzseh  believed  in  a  large  capital,  since  it  gave  the  bank  a 
standing  in  financial  circles  and  also  indicated  that  it  was 
composed  of  thrifty  and  industrious  members.  Consequently 
he  prescribed  no  territorial  limits,  but  allowed  the  banks  to 
operate  through  agents  and  branches  and  as  far  away  from 


276  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

headquarters  as  conveniently  practicable.  He  urged  them 
also  to  gather  members  from  various  trades,  with  the  idea 
that  their  savings  and  earnings  coming  in  at  different  times 
would  steady  the  inflow  of  capital.  He  wished  each  bank  to 
be  the  chief  savings  and  loan  institution  in  its  locality,  and 
many  of  them  have  become  such.  The  only  limit  he  placed 
as  to  size  was  that  the  capital  of  a  bank  should  be  one-tenth 
of  the  amount  of  its  outstanding  obligations  at  the  start,  one- 
fourth  at  the  end  of  the  second  or  third  year  of  its  existence, 
and  finally  one-half.  But  he  restricted  the  holdings  of  each 
member  to  one  share,  so  as  to  prevent  the  bank  from  falling 
into  the  hands  of  rich  people. 

Besides  giving  the  bank  a  financial  standing,  the  capital 
acts  as  a  guaranty  fund  to  protect  members  from  their  per- 
sonal liability.  The  reserve  is  created  to  meet  any  losses 
which  cannot  be  paid  out  of  the  earnings.  Its  source,  in 
addition  to  all  entrance  fees,  is  a  certain  portion  of  the  profits 
sufficient  to  maintain  it  always  at  least  up  to  ten  per  cent  of 
the  capital.  In  a  new  bank  one-fifth  of  the  profits  may  be 
used  for  this  purpose;  in  an  old  institution  five  or  ten  per 
cent  will  suffice,  and  the  balance  of  profits  may  then  be  dis- 
tributed as  dividends.  The  method  of  distribution  varies.  In 
most  banks  it  does  not  begin  until  the  member  has  paid  up  a 
certain  part  of  his  share.  Profits  are  then  credited  on  it, 
but  not  till  it  has  been  fully  paid  does  it  draw  dividends  in 
cash.  Schulze-Delitzsch  believed  in  large  dividends  in  order 
to  encourage  thrift  and  attract  capital.  Six  and  seven  per 
cent  are  not  unusual  now. 

Large  dividends  are  objectionable  and  dangerous  from  the 
cooperative  point  of  view.  They  come  mostly  from  the  bor- 
rowing members  and  add  to  their  burdens,  thus  creating  a 
conflict  of  interests  within  the  bank.  Hence  many  writers 
contend  that  they  should  not  exceed  the  rate  at  which  money 
may  be  procured  in  the  open  market.  Unless  some  such  re- 
striction is  imposed  it  is  difficult  for  a  people's  bank  to  main- 
tain its  true  character.  Por  a  cooperative  association  money 
is  easy  to  get,  especially  when  it  is  large  and  offers  attractive 
profits.     But  when  once  the  ambition  for  large  dividends 


THE  SCHULZE-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    277 

arises,  the  members  who  join  for  gain  predominate  over  those 
who  join  for  obtaining  credit  and  the  bank  is  led  to  place  its 
funds  in  outside  investments.  This  is  particularly  the  case 
■with  a  few  large  concerns  of  the  limited-liability  type,  which 
have  become  veritable  capitalistic  banks  and  use  their  funds 
in  ventures  with  which  their  members  have  no  connection. 

But  as  a  general  rule  the  people's  banks  remaia  faithful 
to  their  members.  Moreover,  the  organization  and  manage- 
ment are  so  arranged  that  cooperative  methods  and  equitable 
treatment  for  all  is  practically  assured.  The  administration 
of  each  bank  is  entrusted  to  an  executive  committee  and  a 
board  of  supervision  elected  at  the  annual  meeting  of  the 
general  assembly.  The  general  assembly  is  composed  of  the 
sh|treholders  of  the  bank,  each  of  whom  has  but  one  vote 
which  cannot  be  balloted  by  proxy.  The  assembly  meets  an- 
nually to  elect  officers,  quarterly  to  review  the  affairs  of  the 
bank,  and  on  special  occasions  when  called  by  the  executive 
committee  or  one-tenth  of  the  members.  The  majority  pre- 
vails, except  in  important  cases  like  changing  the  by-laws 
or  value  of  shares,  removal  of  officers,  or  dissolution,  when 
three-fourths  of  the  votes  of  at  least  one-third  of  the  members 
are  required.  A  person  who  belongs  to  an  unlimited-liability 
bank  cannot  be  a  member  of  any  other  bank. 

The  executive  committee  is  composed  of  the  manager, 
cashier  and  comptroller.  They  must  be  members  and  cannot 
be  elected  for  a  longer  term  than  three  years.  They  transact 
the  actual  business  of  the  bank.  No  business  may  be  done 
outside  of  office  hours  or  without  the  concurrence  of  at 
least  two  of  the  committee.  For  compensation  they  receive 
annual  salaries  and  a  percentage  of  the  profits. 

The  board  of  supervision  usually  consists  of  nine  or  more 
members,  one-third  of  whom  are  retired  each  year.  They 
select  a  chairman  and  may  act  only  by  a  majority  vote.  No 
supervisor  may  take  part  in  any  proceeding  in  which  he  is  per- 
sonally interested.  The  board  meets  once  a  week.  It  receives 
weekly,  monthly  and  quarterly  statements  from  the  execu- 
tive committee  and  supervises  its  official  conduct.  The  board 
and  the  committee  act  jointly  in  granting  credit,  handling 


278  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

the  funds,  borrowing  money  for  the  bank,  suspending  em- 
ployees, admitting  and  expelling  members,  auditing  accounts 
and  preparing  reports  for  the  general  assembly,  and  m  all 
other  matters  of  prime  importance.  The  board  may  tem- 
porarily suspend  the  ezecutive  committee  or  any  part  of  it, 
and  take  entire  charge  of  affairs  imtil  the  general  assembly 
is  called  to  decide  upon  the  case.  The  supervisors  are  com- 
pensated by  fees  paid  for  the  meetings  they  attend. 

By  such  an  administration,  elected  for  a  short  period  and 
subject  to  dismissal  upon  the  vote  of  a  small  minority,  the 
members  may  exercise  absolute  control  over  the  bank,  and 
compel  it  to  be  properly  managed  for  their  exclusive  benefit. 
A  Schulze-Delitzsch  or  people's  bank  does  strictly  a  banking 
business,  receiving  deposits,  extending  credit,  buying  and 
selling  securities  on  commission  for  members,  and  sometimes 
making  collections  for  them.  It  can  own  no  real  estate 
except  for  its  ofiice  building,  and  must  strive  to  avoid  invest- 
ments and  transactions  of  a  speculative  or  hazardous  nature. 
The  funds  for  its  business  are  its  capital,  reserves,  sight  and 
time  deposits  of  members  and  outsiders,  and  money  borrowed 
in  case  of  need  on  the  collective  liability  of  its  members.  It 
uses  these  funds  without  regard  to  origin  in  its  various  opera- 
tions, although  it  endeavors  to  keep  its  reserves  in  easily  nego- 
tiable securities. 

The  credit  facilities  of  a  bank  are  for  its  members  only, 
and  small  are  preferred  to  large  loans,  lio  member  of  the 
executive  committee  may  receive  credit.  Supervisors  may 
receive  credit  if  approved  by  a  committee  specially  appointed 
to  consider  the  matter.  Outside  investments  are  made  only 
to  prevent  funds  from  lying  idle  or  to  place  reserves  in  safe 
securities.  But  although  the  bank  is  run  for  the  benefit  of 
members,  they  cannot  make  use  of  its  services  unless  they 
prove  themselves  worthy  of  them.  In  the  large  societies  the 
executive  committee,  with  the  assistance  of  the  board  of 
supervision,  prepares  a  list,  register,  or  card  catalogue  on 
which  are  recorded  opposite  the  names  of  the  members  all 
facts  bearing  on  their  solvency  and  the  maximum  of  credit 
that  may  be  accorded  to  each.     The  latter  figure  increases 


THE  SCHIJLZB-DELITZSCH  PEOPLE'S  BANKS    379 

with  the  payments  made  on  the  shares,  but  this  is  not  defin- 
itive. Each  ease  depends  on  its  individual  merits  and  secur- 
ity is  required.  Eeal-estate  mortgages  and  members'  shares 
are  rarely  taken  and  some  banks  do  not  aUow  them  at  all. 
Chattel  mortgages,  pledges  of  not  easily  perishable  personal 
property,  warehouse  receipts,  biUs  of  lading,  collateral  and 
bankable  paper  are  frequent,  but  the  most  customary  and 
desirable  security  is  the  indorsement  of  two  or  more  friends, 
usually  fellow  members. 

The  people's  bank  gives  all  kinds  of  credit.  They  make 
loans  on  an  I.  0.  U.  or  promissory  note  and  discount  book 
debts  and  bills  of  exchange.  But  the  two  methods  which 
seem  to  be  preferred  are  accepting  bills  of  exchange  and 
graptiug  advances  on  current  accounts,  or  cash  credit.  In 
the  former  of  these  two  methods,  a  member  draws  a  biU  on 
his  bank  iu  favor  of  his  creditor.  The  bank  writes  its  accept- 
ance for  a  small  fee  across  the  face  of  the  biU.  The  creditor 
indorses  and  sells  it  at  some  other  bank  or  otherwise  disposes 
of  it  in  the  course  of  his  business.  By  thus  using  its  name 
and  financial  standing  the  accepting  bank  can  accommodate 
members  without  passing  over  a  cent  of  its  funds,  while  mem- 
bers may  make  use  of  their  credit  as  actual  money.  Cash 
credit  is  practised  ia  the  same  way  as  in  Scotland,  but  the 
current  account  on  which  the  cash  payments  are  debited  and 
credited  is  closed  every  six  months.  The  time  on  all  other 
forms  of  credit  is  generally  three  months.  Punctuality  is 
rigorously  exacted,  but  renewals  are  allowed  wherever  equity 
or  necessity  demand  them. 

Schulze-Delitzsch  opposed  centralization  and  so  no  sys- 
tem has  been  created  out  of  his  banks.  The  "Federation  of 
Industrial  and  Economical  Cooperative  Societies  based  on  the 
Principle  of  Self-help,"  or  General  Federation,  which  was 
proposed  at  his  first  convention  in  1859  and  assumed  definite 
shape  in  1864,  does  not  prevent  independent  action,  nor  does 
it  interfere  in  the  internal  affairs  of  the  societies.  Schulze- 
DeHtzsch  believed,  however,  that  the  banks  should  unite  by 
provinces  in  Prussia  and  by  states  or  groups  of  small  states 
in  the  rest  of  Germany,  and  all  are  now  grouped  together 


280  EUEAL    CREDITS 

in  this  fashion  under  the  Federation.  Three  of  these  groups 
founded  provincial  banks,  and  Schulze-Delitzseh  helped  to 
start  a  central  bank  at  Berlin,  but  only  a  minority  of  the 
banks  joined.  In  1868  he  organized  a  Bureau  of  Exchange 
to  facilitate  financial  relations  between  the  societies.  This 
stiU  exists,  and  with  the  assistance  of  the  Dresdner  Bank, 
which  has  established  a  special  department  for  the  credit 
societies,  takes  care  of  whatever  transactions  they  carry  on 
among  themselves. 


CHAPTEE   XXII 

THE    EAIFPEISEN   SYSTEM 

Life  and  Character  of  EaifPeisen. — Early  Work  for  Cooperation. — 
Change  from  Charity  to  Self-help.— Growth  of  Societies. — Dif- 
ferences from  Sehulze-Delitzsch  System. — Central  Agricultural 
Land  Bank. — General  Federation  of  the  Eural  Cooperative  So- 
cieties.— ^Reasons  for  Success  of  His  Principles. — Agricultural 
Cooperation  and  Combination  His  Contribution. 

Frederick  William  Henry  Eaiffeisen  was  born  on 
March  30,  1810,  at  Hamm  in  the  Ehine  Province,  Germany. 
In  his  ancestry,  traced  back  to  1569,  there  were  many  teach- 
ers, ministers  and  burgomasters.  His  mother  was  a  devout 
Christian  woman  of  strong  character.  His  father,  once  a 
clergyman  and  mayor  of  this  little  village,  was  addicted  to 
drink,  became  demented  from  alcoholic  excesses  and  died  in 
1821,  leaving  his  widow  and  children  in  poor  circumstances. 
Young  Eaiffeisen  was  inclined  to  religion  from  childhood  and 
was  confirmed  in  the  Evangelical  or  Lutheran  faith  in  1832. 
Poverty  prevented  his  going  to  college  but  the  pastor  of  his 
church,  attracted  by  his  studious  habits,  instructed  him  for 
several  years  after  he  left  the  village  school  and  gave  him  a 
good  education  in  the  rudiments  of  learning. 

At  the  age  of  seventeen  he  joined  the  army.  In  1835  he 
was  a  volunteer  in  an  artillery  brigade  stationed  at  the  for- 
tress of  Cologne,  whence  he  was  sent  in  1838  to  the  army 
school  at  Coblenz,  where  he  stayed  two  years,  studying 
mathematics,  physics,  chemistry,  and  other  subjects.  After 
passing  the  examinations,  he  was  made  a  master  artificer  in 
1840,  and  was  detailed  the  following  year  to  the  royal  foundry 
of  the  Sayn  where  the  Government  cast  cannon.  Shortly 
afterward  he  was  afflicted  with  a  disease  of  the  eyes  which 

281 


282  ETJEAL    CREDITS 

threatened  blindness  and  had  to  quit  the  army  and  give  up  his 
hopes  of  becoming  a  commissioned  officer. 

Eaiffeisen  then  entered  the  civil  service  and  obtained  a 
clerkship  under  the  municipal  government  of  Coblenz,  through 
the  influence  of  an  uncle  who  was  a  prominent  lawyer. 
In  1843  he  was  appointed  secretary  of  the  congressional 
district  of  Mayen,  in  which  office  he  displayed  such  marked 
administrative  abilities  and  attention  to  duties  that  he 
was  elected  in  1846  the  burgomaster  or  mayor  of  Weyer- 
busch,  to  which  Flammersfeld  with  its  33  villages  was  added 
in  1848.  His  first  marriage  occurred  in  1849,  and  of  this 
union  were  born  seven  children,  two  of  whom  became  well 
known,  his  son  Eudolf,  who  succeeded  him  as  the  head  of  his 
cooperative  system,  and  his  daughter,  Amelia,  who  acted  as 
his  faithfid  amanuensis  and  assistant  manager  of  his  affairs, 
public  and  private,  during  the  years  of  his  partial  blindness 
until  his  death. 

In  1852  Eaiffeisen  was  elected  mayor  of  Heddesdorf,  one 
of  the  boroughs  of  the  city  of  Neuwied.  After  this  date  his 
eight  failed  rapidly  and  his  health,  which  had  never  been 
good,  broke  down  completely.  He  suffered  from  rheumatism 
and  congestion  of  the  brain  and  was  troubled  by  vague  fears 
and  premonition  of  death.  His  deeply  religious  spirit  became 
morbidly  intensified  and  Amelia  often  found  him  on  his 
knees  in  prayer.  His  opinionated  and  obstinate  disposition, 
which  was  always  hard  for  others  to  bear,  grew  worse,  and 
his  superiors  were  quite  willing,  if  not  anxious,  to  be  rid  of 
him.  His  reelection  as  mayor  in  1863  was  not  confirmed  by 
the  Government,  so  he  retired  from  public  office  in  1865  on 
an  annual  pension  of  about  $300  and  the  possession  of  a  very 
small  estate. 

Obliged  to  begin  life  anew  at  55  years  of  age,  Eaiffeisen 
settled  at  Heddesdorf  and  started  a  little  cigar  factory.  Not 
getting  satisfactory  returns  he  closed  this  out.  He  then  sold 
life  insurance  and  opened  up  a  wine  agency,  which  continued 
to  be  his  means  of  livelihood  for  many  years.  He  ran  in  debt 
for  a  while  and  then  began  to  prosper.  But  money-making 
was  of  only  secondary  importance  to  him,  and  thenceforth  he 


THE   EAIFFEISEN    SYSTEM  283 

gave  practically  all  his  time,  energy  and  fortune  to  organiz- 
ing rural  cooperative  credit  societies.  In  1866  he  published  a 
book,  explaining  the  principles  and  practices  of  such  societies, 
which  had  a  vdde  circulation  and  went  through  a  number  of 
editions.  In  1868  he  married  again,  his  first  wife  having 
died  in  1863. 

In  1882  Emperor  William  I  sent  him  a  letter  in  apprecia- 
tion of  his  great  work  in  helping  the  farmers,  accompanied  by 
a  donation  of  about  $7,200.  A  similar  mark  of  respect  was 
shown  by  the  present  Emperor,  William  II,  who  gave  him 
about  $4,800.  Early  in  1888  EaifBeisen  became  fatally  ill 
at  his  home  in  Heddesdorf,  but  kept  his  mind  clear  till  the 
end.  On  March  2,  after  attending  to  the  routine  affairs  of 
the  day,  feeling  the  approach  of  death,  he  devoted  himself' 
to  prayer  and  calmly  passed  away.  His  statue  stands  ia  front 
of  his  house  in  Heddesdorf.  The  Crown  Prince  and  other 
notables  of  the  Empire,  prominent  representatives  from  Euro- 
pean countries,  and  thousands  of  German  farmers  were  pres- 
ent at  its  unveiliug  in  1902.  He  is  revered  in  Germany  as 
the  patron  saint  of  agriculture. 

Eaiffeisen  was  harsh  and  rigorous,  with  an  irascible  tem- 
per easily  inflamed  to  anger  by  contradiction  or  opposition, 
so  he  did  not  have  many  iutimate  friends.  He  presented  a 
stem  appearance  with  his  almost  sightless  eyes,  but  his  de- 
meanor was  singularly  pleasing  when  he  relaxed  himself  in 
occasional  recreation  from  his  arduous  and  constant  labors,  or 
was  engaged  in  conversation  with  persons  who  did  not  dispute 
his  views.  Habitually  he  was  taciturn  and  moody.  He  had 
a  weak  voice  and  slight  talent  for  public  speaking,  yet  made 
a  strong  impression  upon  his  audiences  by  the  earnest  and 
logical  manner  of  his  address.  His  book  learning  was  meager, 
since  all  his  reading  and  writing  had  to  be  done  through 
others  on  account  of  his  semi-blindness,  hence  his  ideas  were 
mostly  original  with  himself.  He  was  a  worker  rather  than 
a  student.  His  strength  lay  in  his  indomitable  will,  his 
persistent  fidelity  to  ideals,  his  ability  to  toil  hard  and  long 
and  to  make  practical  use  of  whatever  theoretical  knowledge 
he  possessed,  and  above  aU  in  his  deeply  religious  nature 


384  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

and  charitable  spirit  wMch  made  him  look  upon  his  self- 
imposed  task  of  uplifting  the  poor  as  a  divine  mission. 

"Inasmuch  as  ye  have  done  it  unto  one  of  the  least  of 
these  my  brethren,  ye  have  done  it  unto  me,"  was  his  life's 
motto,  and  he  denied  himself  ordiaary  comforts,  traveled 
third-class  and  stopped  at  cheap  hotels  that  he  might  save 
money  to  carry  out  his  mission.  As  he  went  up  and  down 
the  country  and  visited  his  credit  societies,  the  members  called 
him  "good  father  EaifEeisen,"  and  many  Catholic  priests 
and  Protestant  ministers  acknowledged  that  his  work  for  co- 
operation had  more  moral  effect  on  the  peasantry  than  all 
their  sermons  and  ministrations.  But  the  plans  of  this 
kindly,  cranky,  half-blind,  poor  and  chronically  sick  philan- 
thropist would  often  have  gone  awry  had  it  not  been  for  his 
daughter  Amelia  and  several  wise  friends  to  whose  advice 
alone  he  would  listen. 

Eaiffeisen's  work  for  cooperation  did  not  begin  in  earnest 
until  about  a  year  prior  to  his  retirement  from  public  of&ce, 
although  long  before  that  time  he  had  made  a  name  for  him- 
self locally  by  organizing  associations  which  exhibited  coop- 
erative features.  In  1846  he  formed  at  Weyerbusch  an  asso- 
ciation for  buying  food  and  another  for  baking  and  selling 
bread  to  the  destitute.  In  1847  he  formed  an  association  to 
supply  peasants  with  wheat  and  potatoes  for  planting,  and  in 
1849  another  to  lend  money  to  peasants  around  Flammers- 
f eld  and  to  sell  them  cattle  to  be  paid  for  in  five  annual  instal- 
ments. Famine  was  stalking  through  the  land  during  this 
period.  It  had  decimated  the  population  and  put  the  farm- 
ing and  working  classes  in  abject  want.  Eaiffeisen  was 
mayor,  the  chief  civil  head  of  the  local  government,  and  he 
considered  it  his  public  as  well  as  his  moral  duty  to  alleviate 
this  suffering.  His  associations  reduced  the  price  of  bread 
fifty  per  cent,  and  brought  about  the  expected  relief.  But  they 
were  not,  strictly  speaking,  cooperative.  They  were  simply 
groups  of  benevolent  persons  who  out  of  charity  admitted  to 
their  benefits  such  of  their  imfortunate  brethren  as  were 
worthy  of  help,  and  they  were  used  only  for  the  poor.  The 
beneficiaries  had  no  voice  in  their  management. 


THE   EAIFFEISEN    SYSTEM  285 

The  association  at  Flammersfeld  illustrates  the  type  of 
credit  society  with  which  Eaiffeisen  began.  It  was  composed 
of  60  wealthy  citizens  of  the  place,  induced  to  join  perhaps 
because  of  Raiffeisen's  political  power  and  influence  as  mayor. 
SiQce  they  rendered  themselves  liable  for  all  debts  incurred, 
he  allowed  them  the  entire  control  and  the  right  to  decide 
who  should  be  members  and  receive  loans.  In  1854  he 
founded  at  Heddesdorf  his  second  credit  society  along  similar 
lines.  Besides  lending  to  peasants  who  were  in  the  clutches 
of  usurers,  the  Heddesdorf  society  attempted  to  find  homes 
for  abandoned  children,  give  employment  to  mendicants,  per- 
suade the  shiftless  to  work,  and  establish  a  free  library.  This 
ambitious  scheme  proved  a  failure  and  was  abandoned  after 
a  few  years'  trial. 

Indeed  Eaiffeisen  had  trouble  with  every  one  of  his  early 
societies,  ovsdng  to  the  fact  that  their  rich  supporters  would 
not  give  them  any  personal  service  after  the  enthusiasm  he 
inspired  had  died  away.  He  realized  eventually  that  charity 
by  itself  has  no  lasting  effect  and  that  he  would  have  to 
utilize  more  largely  the  principle  of  self-help.  One  of  Eaif- 
feisen's  letters  on  this  subject  showing  that  he  reached  this 
conclusion  after  studying  Schulze-Delitzsch's  work  has  been 
given  in  a  previous  chapter.  In  another  written  in  the  same 
vein  he  said:  "I  have  decided  to  form  a  society  upon  this 
plan  [of  self-help].  The  thing  has  succeeded  perfectly  in 
the  societies  founded  by  Schulze-Delitzsch." 

This  new  society  was  started  in  1864  at  Heddesdorf  with 
the  sole  object  of  granting  loans  to  members  recruited  within 
that  locality,  but  it  was  preceded  by  two  years  by  the  mutual 
credit  society  at  Anhausen  for  the  organization  of  which 
Eaiffeisen  was  only  partly  responsible.  The  Anhausen  so- 
ciety not  only  accorded  credit  but  also  bought  fertilizers,  seed 
and  oil-cake  to  sell  to  members,  with  the  hope,  as  announced 
by  its  chief  organizer,  that  weU-to-do  persons  not  lq  need  of 
loans  would  be  attracted  to  become  members  by  the  cheap  , 
wholesale  prices  of  these  commodities  and  thus  strengthen  the 
standing  of  the  society.  This  dual  function  subsequently  be- 
came one  of  the  characteristic  features  of  a  German  rural- 


286  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

credit  society,  but  its  adoption  by  Eaiffeisen  did  not  occur 
until  June  13,  1869,  when  his  Heddesdorf  loan  association 
by  resolution  dated  April  25  of  the  same  year  was  reorganized 
on  the  lines  of  the  Anhausen  society.  Eaiffeisen  at  the  same 
time  eliminated  the  urban  population  from  his  consideration 
and  confined  his  attention  entirely  to  the  farming  classes. 
Hence,  1869  is  the  year  from  which  his  rural  cooperative 
credit  movement  should  be  dated; 

Progress  was  slow,  for  he  dealt  with  a  densely  ignorant 
and  poverty-stricken  people  inherently  distrustful  of  innova- 
tions, and  Eaiffeisen  had  to  build  up  from  the  very  ground. 
The  Heddesdorf  society  stood  alone  until  1868  when  five 
others  were  formed.  Twenty-two  more  were  added  in  1869. 
After  1880  the  number  began  steadily  to  increase  and  at  the 
time  of  Eaiffeisen's  death  there  were  425  of  his  societies  in 
existence.  Between  1890  and  1894  the  growth  was  very 
rapid.  In  1912  there  was  in  Germany  one  rural  cooperative 
association  for  every  2,494  inhabitants  and  for  every  3,365 
acres  of  agricultural  land,  and  two-thirds  of  these  were  credit 
societies,  not  aU,  however,  of  the  pure  Eaiffeisen  type. 

In  substitutiug  Sehulze-Delitzsch's  self-help  idea  for  char- 
ity, Eaiffeisen  did  not  accept  his  rival's  methods  of  organiza- 
tion and  business,  nor  did  he  surrender  his  own  conviction 
that  the  rich  and  the  well-to-do  should  join  with  the  poor  in 
order  to  give  standing  to  the  credit  societies.  Indeed  he 
firmly  adhered  to  his  original  arrangement  in  this  particular 
and  continued  to  insist  that  the  wealthy  members  should  be 
accorded  a  voice  in  the  management  proportioned  to  the  in- 
crease of  strength  which  they  added  to  the  societies  by  becom- 
ing members.  TTnlike  Schulze-Delitzseh,  Eaiffeisen  was  not 
afraid  of  the  wealthy  and  powerful,  because,  as  will  be  seen 
later,  his  organization  was  such  as  to  prevent  their  exercising 
any  undue  influence,  even  if  the  societies  had  the  good  for- 
tune to  induce  large  numbers  of  them  to  come  in. 
/■  Indeed,  the  systems  evolved  by  these  two  founders  of  co- 
/operative  credit  differ  in  so  many  respects  that  it  is  quite  im- 
( possible  for  them  to  act  in  harmony,  although  they  have  the 
■  same  object  of  creating  credit  for  small  amounts  on  the  col- 


THE   EAIFFEISEN   SYSTEM  287 

lectivity  of  borrowers.  Schulze-Delitzsch  believed  in  a  large, 
mixed  membership  drawn  from  an  imrestrieted  area,  Eaif- 
feisen  in  a  small  membership  of  one  class  confined  to  an  area 
containing  not  more  than  3,000  inhabitants.  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  believed  in  fair  salaries  and  compensation, 
Eaiffeisen,  in  gratuitous  service.  Schulze-Delitzsch  believed 
that  a  society  should  declare  as  large  dividends  as 
possible-;  Eaiffeisen,  that  it  should  make  no  distribution  of 
profit.  Schulze-Delitzsch  believed  that  a  society  should  do 
a  general  banking  business  on  three  months'  paper,  and 
he  abandoned  the  idea  of  watching  the  use  of  the  money; 
Eaiffeisen  favored  only  the  simplest  kind  of  transactions  and 
long-time  loans  running  for  years  if  necessary  and  amortiza- 
ble  or  repayable  by  instalments,  and  he  permitted  loans  to  be 
granted  for  productive  purposes  alone.  Schulze-Delitzsch  be- 
lieved in  entrance  fees  and  shares  of  such  size  as  to  keep  out 
persons  who  did  not  possess  a  few  assets  or  a  small  income. 
Eaiffeisen  was  opposed  to  a  capital  formed  by  the  shares  of 
members  and  withdrawable  at  wiU  on  a  short  notice.  He 
placed  in  its  stead  what  he  called  the  indivisible  reserve,  ac- 
cumidated  from  slight  additions  to  the  interest  rate  of  the 
loans,  which  remained  the  permanent  property  of  the  society, 
to  be  used  as  a  guaranty  and  also  as  a  working  fund  and  in 
case  of  dissolution  to  be  turned  over  to  some  new  credit  so- 
ciety which  might  be  organized  in  the  locality.  As  to  mem- 
bers, he  welcomed  anyone  whose  character  was  vouched  for 
by  neighbors,  even  if  he  did  not  have  a  cent  to  his  name. 

Finally,  the  aim  of  the  societies  of  Schulze-Delitzsch  was 
purely  materialistic,  while  the  aim  of  Eaiffeisen's  associa- 
tions was  humanitarian.  In  fact  Eaiffeisen  was  a  layman 
preacher,  teaching  non-confessional  Christianity  and  broth- 
erly love,  and  he  strove  to  make  each  of  his  societies  a  center 
of  educational  and  moral  influence  in  its  little  community,  as 
well  as  a  source  from  which  its  members  might  obtain  credit, 
money  and  all  other  things  needed  for  acquiring  and  improv- 
ing their  farms  and  carrying  on  enterprises  of  an  agricul- 
tural nature.  Inasmuch  as  he  knew  that  unlimited  liability 
was  the  best  way  to  inspire  mutual  trust  and  enforce  mutual 


288  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

self-help,  lie  did  not  temporize  with  it  as  Sehulze-Delitzseh 
did,  but  made  it  a  cardinal  principle.  Furthermore,  he  wished 
to  create  a  complete  solidarity  of  interest  in  the  class  for 
whom  he  toiled;  hence  he  strove  to  erect  a  great  centralized 
system  with  himself  as  the  supreme  dictatorial  head,  while 
Schulze-Delitzsch  thought  that  every  society  should  take  care 
of  itself  and  join  others  only  for  convenience  of  exchange, 
propaganda,  and  standardizing  methods  and  practices. 
"^  The  chief  point  in  which  the  EaifEeisen  society  differed 
in  form  from  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  type  was  its  absence  of 
shares,  but  after  Schulze-Delitzsch  had  forced  his  views  upon 
the  legislature  and  the  second  German  law  on  cooperation  was 
passed  in  1889,  requiriag  a  capital  stock,  they,  became  prac- 
tically alike  in  regard  to  organization  and  administration. 
As  required  by  this  law,  all  Eaiffeiscn  societies  now  have 
share  capital,  but  this  fact  has  not  caused  any  change  in 
the  original  spirit  and  purpose.  The  size  of  the  share  is 
fixed  at  $2.50;  it  may  be  bought  on  time,  so  that  the  mem- 
ber need  not  put  up  a  cent  on  joining,  since  entrance  fees 
are  not  exacted.  The  dividend  on  this  small  share  is  never 
allowed  to  exceed  the  rate  of  interest  charged  to  members  on 
loans,  and  in  the  great  majority  of  cases  none  is  distributed  in 
cash,  but  the  sum  due  each  shareholder  is  used  for  paying  his 
subscription  to  the  Federation's  periodicals.  The  profits  of  the 
society  are  used,  first,  to  make  good  any  impairment  that  the 
paid-up  capital  may  have  suffered,  one-fiJth  of  the  remainder 
is  devoted  to  social  welfare  work,  and  the  rest  is  transferred  to 
the  reserves.  The  reserves  consist  of  a  fund  to  cover  annual 
losses  and  another  known  as  the  foundation  fimd.  No 
figure  is  fixed  for  their  size,  but  they  are  allowed  to  accumu- 
late until  they  are  large  enough  to  supply  the  society  with 
the  necessary  working  capital,  make  it  independent  of  outside 
assistance,  and  enable  it  to  support  some  object  of  general 
utUity  for  the  benefit  of  the  members.  Both  funds  are  in- 
divisible, that  is,  in  the  event  of  dissolution  they  are  not  dis- 
tributed among  the  members  but  are  turned  over  to  the 
Central  Bank  of  the  system  for  organizing  a  new  society  in 
the  same  place.    If  no  society  is  formed  within  30  years,  they 


THE   EAIPFEISEF    SYSTEM  289 

become  the  property  of  the  communej  to  be  applied  to  some 
local  public  purpose. 

The  committee  of  management  of  a  local  society  consists 
of  three  members  elected  for  four  years,  two  or  three  of  them 
retiring  every  two  years;  it  meets  once  a  month.  The  board 
of  supervision  consists  of  three  to  nine  members  elected  for 
three  years,  one-third  retiring  each  year;  it  meets  regularly 
four  times  a  year.  Their  duties  correspond  with  the  duties  of 
similar  officers  in  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  societies,  with  the  ad- 
dition that  the  managers  must  oversee  the  use  of  loans  and 
attend  to  whatever  buying  and  selling  is  done  by  the  society. 
The  only  paid  officer  is  the  secretary,  appointed  by  the  mem- 
bers for  four  years,  who  acts  as  bookkeeper  and  treasuser ;  he 
may  not  be  a  member  of  either  the  board  or  the  committee. 
The  unlimited  liability  assumed  by  the  members  runs  directly 
in  favor  of  the  creditors  as  well  as  of  the  society.  Eetire- 
ments  are  allowed  on  six;  weeks'  notice  to  take  efEect  at  the 
end  of  the  year.  The  members  meet  regularly  once  in  the 
spring  and  again  in  the  fall.  The  majority  prevails,  except 
that  a  three-fourths'  vote  is  required  for  dismissing  man- 
agers, altering  the  articles  of  agreement  or  dissolving  the  so- 
ciety. These  meetings  are  held  not  only  for  transaetiag  busi- 
ness but  also  for  hearing  lectures,  exchanging  views  and  dis- 
cussing matters  of  general  interest. 

Besides  granting  credit  to  members  and  receiving  de- 
posits, the  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies  may  undertake  the  pur- 
chase ia  common  of  farm  supplies,  machinery  and  breeding 
animals  to  be  used  in  common,  the  sale  in  common  of  farm 
produce  and  the  purchase  of  tracts  of  land  to  be  resold  to 
members.  The  purchases  do  not  include  groceries  or  house- 
hold necessities.  They  are  confined  to  such  commodities  as 
seed,  fertilizer,  machines,  coal,  etc.,  by  the  car  load  at  whole- 
sale prices,  and  all  may  be  bought  from  the  society  by  the 
members  on  time.  This  commercial  business  is  on  the  in- 
crease, and  as  a  result  a  great  deal  of  credit  is  extended  on 
current  accounts.  Loans  of  over  one  year  must  be  repaid 
in  annual  instalments  or  in  sums  of  which  the  principal  is  a 
multiple.    Shorter  loans  may  be  renewed  by  periods  of  three 


290  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

months  up  to  two  years.  The  times  of  payment  are  fixed  to 
suit  the  borrower  and  the  purpose  of  the  loan.  The  society 
reserves  the  right  to  recall  all  loans  on  four  weeks'  notice  and 
always  requires  security.  The  least  security  accepted  is  the 
indorsement  of  some  guarantor  known  to  be  good  for  the 
amount.  On  real-estate  mortgages  two-thirds  of  the  value  of 
the  property  is  the  limit. 

Eaiffeisen  required  each  of  his  credit  societies  to  become  a 
shareholder  in  the  Central  Agricultural-  Loan  Bank  and  a 
member  of  the  General  Federation  of  the  Eural  Cooperative 
Societies  of  Germany  and  of  the  union  thereunder  to  which 
it  shoiild  be  assigned,  and  also  to  buy  its  supplies  from 
Eaiffeisen,  Fassbender  and  Company.  He  was  the  managing 
head  of  these  three  institutions  and  formed  them  in  accord- 
ance with  his  aim  of  bringing  about  the  consolidation  of  the 
interests  of  all  German  farmers  by  means  of  a  great  central- 
ized system.  The  firm  of  Eaiffeisen,  Fassbender  and  Com- 
pany, consisting  of  his  daughter  Amelia,  an  adviser  and  him- 
self, was  formed  by  Eaiffeisen  in  1881  by  turning  over  to  it  his 
wine  business,  the  general  agency  he  held  of  a  large  life- 
insurance  company,  and  $3,120  in  cash.  It  sold  the  wine 
business  and  bought  a  press  for  doing  the  printing  of  the 
unions  and  publishing  the  journal  of  the  Federation.  But 
its  principal  business  was  to  buy  supplies  at  wholesale  or  on 
commission  to  sell  to  the  associations.  The  profits  were  used 
entirely  for  paying  salaries  and  expenses  of  the  ofiBcers  and 
employees  of  the  system  and  for  creating  a  permanent  fund 
for  perpetuating  the  work.  The  Central  Bank  took  over  this 
firm  in  1899  and  in  1909  sold  assets  and  good  will  to  the 
unions,  which  thereupon  organized  cooperative  societies  with 
limited  liability  to  handle  their  part  of  its  business. 

The  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  was  organized  in 
1876.  Three  provincial  banks  and  a  general  bank  had  been 
founded  in  1872  and  1874,  but  they  were  dissolved  by  the 
courts  because  the  laws  at  that  time  did  not  allow  one  asso- 
ciation to  combine  with  another  nor  an  association  without 
shares  to  do  a  banking  business.  Consequently  the  Central 
Agricultural  Loan  Bank  was  formed  as  a  joint-stock  com- 


THE   RAIFFEISEN"    SYSTEM  291 

pany  and  at  the  start  its  shares  were  held  by  of&cials  in 
trust  for  the  system.  The  present  capital  is  $2,400,000, 
divided  into  shares  of  $240  each,  which  may  be  held  only  by 
credit  societies  and  the  Bank's  officials.  The  largest  holding 
is  five  shares.  The  bank  has  13  branches  and  is  managed  by 
a  president,  an  advisory  council  consisting  of  the  heads  of  the 
branches,  and  a  board  of  supervision  composed  of  representa- 
tives from  each  union.  The  president  is  selected  by  the  board 
from  among  the  members  of  the  council.  The  branches  have 
advisory  councils  of  their  own  and  all  business  with  the  local 
associations  is  done  through  them.  Formerly  the  Central 
Agricultural  Loan  Bank  dealt  only  with  credit  societies  and 
as  a  result  a  number  of  provincial  banks  were  formed  for  the 
other  societies,  but  now  its  facilities  are  open  to  any  kind  of 
association  in  the  system.  Dividends  in  excess  of  four  per 
cent  are  never  declared,  since  the  bank  is  not  run  for  profit. 

The  General  Federation  of  the  Eural  Cooperative  Socie- 
ties of  Germany  was  formed  in  1877  for  the  purpose  of 
protecting  the  interests  of  the  societies,  giving  advice  and 
carrying  on  the  work  of  propaganda  and  organization.  It 
owns  a  library  and  press,  and  since  the  firm  of  EaifEeisen, 
Fassbender  and  Company  went  out  of  existence  it  has  printed 
and  published  the  bimonthly  paper,  the  almanac,  annual 
reports,  blank  forms  and  pamphlets  of  useful  agricultural 
information.  It  trains  employees  and  has  obtained  contracts 
with  insurance  companies  for  cheap  rates  for  farmers.  For- 
merly it  received  state  aid,  but  now  its  sources  of  income  are 
the  sale  of  its  printing  and  literature,  commissions  on  insur- 
ance and  contributions  from  adherents  and  from  the  Central 
Agricultural  Loan  Bank.  Under  the  Federation  are  groups 
of  local  societies  called  imions.  The  number  of  unions  is  13 
and  the  larger  are  divided  into  sub-unions. 

The  unions  are  in  reality  provincial  federations  and  they 
have  assumed  great  importance  since  the  law  of  1889  gave 
them  the  right  to  appoint  official  auditors  for  their  local 
societies.  The  officers  are  usually  identical  with  the  officers 
of  the  branches  of  the  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  and 
are  the  active  and  prominent  members  through  whom  the 


S92  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

Federation  does  most  of  its  work  for  strengthening  and  ex- 
tending the  system.  Originally  the  unions  were  simply  parts 
of  the  Federation  but  in  1905  they  all  became  independent 
bodies  with  their  own  charters  or  articles  of  agreement. 

Many  cooperative  societies  for  production,  distribution 
and  other  purposes  sprang  up  in  Germany  along  Eaiffeisen's 
lines  during  his  lifetime  but  he  did  not  pay  much  attention 
to  them.  His  heart  was  with  the  credit  associations  alone. 
He  wished  each  to  embrace  all  the  activities  of  its  members; 
to  serve  as  their  medium  for  the  purchase  of  agricultural  sup- 
plies and  equipment  and  for  the  sale  of  farm  produce;  and 
to  be  their  meeting  place  for  settling  disputes,  exchanging 
views  and  experiences  and  gathering  useful  information,  and 
their  social  center  for  improving  their  intellectual,  moral  and 
material  welfare,  for  helping  their  weak  brethren,  strengthen- 
ing the  love  of  home  and  country  among  themselves,  and 
radiating  a  compelling  influence  for  the  general  good  upon 
the  entire  rural  population  within  the  small  area  of  its  opera- 
tions. This  comprehensive  and  humanitarian  plan,  devised 
by  the  founder,  is  still  followed  in  Germany,  and  the  last 
model  articles  of  agreement  for  credit  societies  (1910)  dis- 
tinctly state  that  they  must  rest  upon  a  Christian  and  pa- 
triotic basis. 

It  is  quite  easy,  of  course,  to  get  the  poor  and  those 
who  want  to  borrow  to  join  a  society  of  such  scope  and  spirit, 
but  what  inducement  is  there  for  the  prosperous  and  well-to- 
do  to  become  members?  Why  should  an  owner  of  a  quarter 
section  of  fertile  land,  in  no  need  of  a  loan,  pool  fortunes 
with  an  ignorant  tiller  of  a  five-acre  patch  enciunbered  with 
debt?  Yet  Eaiffeisen  always  urged  the  big  and  the  little, 
the  rich  and  the  poor,  to  come  together,  and  today  the 
thousands  of  German  societies  of  his  type  contain  all  these 
elements  and  are  usually  managed  as  an  act  of  grace  by  the 
members  who  are  financially  the  stronger.  How  has  this 
marvel  been  accomplished?  The  reason  is  plain.  The  so- 
cieties, in  addition  to  their  splendid  credit  and  banking  fa- 
cilities created  by  provincial  and  national  interrelations,  fur- 
nish cheap  and  convenient  means  of  trade  in  agricultural 


THE   EAIFFEISEK    SYSTEM  293 

necessities,  and  are  so  inherently  safe  and  sound  because  of 
their  organic  arrangement  that  never  once  has  a  local  society 
occasioned  loss  to  a  depositor  or  creditor  nor  a  caU  for  unequal 
assessment  on  members  to  meet  its  obligations.  This  proof 
of  the  practical  lack  of  risk  and  the  suasion  exerted  by  ele- 
vating the  moral  tone,  educating  the  business  sense,  and  bind- 
ing in  complete  solidarity  the  social  and  material  interests  of 
the  farmers  of  the  neighborhood,  attract  and  even  force  aU 
classes,  without  regard  to  their  financial  standing,  to  seek 
admittance  to  the  societies. 

The  poor  are  not  afraid  of  the  rich  for  only  one  vote  is 
allowed  a  member.  Indeed,  since  the  right  to  withdraw  may 
be  exercised  on  a  few  weeks'  notice,  the  poor  are  inclined  to 
be  conservative  and  to  yield  the  control  to  the  rich,  because 
if  the  latter  should  desert  in  numbers  the  society  might  be 
dissolved  and  the  poor  forfeit  to  the  public  whatever  they 
had  paid  into  the  reserves.  The  unlimited  liability,  which 
still  remains  the  corner-stone  of  the  EaifEeisen  system,  is 
harder  on  the  poor  than  on  the  rich,  as  assessments  for  losses 
are  made  share  and  share  alike  and  might  completely  wipe 
out  a  small  estate  without  noticeably  diminishing  a  large 
one.  Hence  unlimited  liability  is  safer  for  the  rich  than 
for  the  poor  in  the  society,  but  it  gives  rise  to  no  fear  or 
anxiety  in  agricultural  regions,  where  alone,  indeed,  it  seems 
possible  to  be  practised,  because  there  the  risk  is  so  remote 
as  to  be  merely  theoretical. 

The  members  of  a  Eaiffeisen  society,  it  must  be  remem- 
bered, are  all  neighbors,  carefully  selected  on  account  of  their 
good  characters,  iudustrious  habits  and  friendly  dispositions. 
The  shiftless  and  quarrelsome  are  barred..  All  have  some 
visible  and  tangible  assets,  their  farms,  or,  if  they  be  only  ten- 
ants, livestock  and  equipment,  so  that  if  one  of  them 
receives  a  loan,  he  wiU  likely  be  able  to  repay  it,  because 
the  ofiBcers  who  are  intimately  acquainted  with  him  know 
beforehand  whether  he  is  good  for  the  amount  and  besides 
they  see  that  he  uses  the  loan  for  the  specified  productive 
purpose  for  which  it  was  granted.  But  if  their  judgment 
should  be  wrong  or  the  crop  or  venture  fail,  there  are  many 


294  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

expedients  to  which  the  society  may  resort  before  calluig 
on  the  members'  unlimited  liability.  In  the  first  place,  if  the 
property  of  the  borrower  brings  nothing  on  execution,  the 
society  may  sue  his  indorsers.  Then,  if  by  any  chance  a 
deficiency  remains,  it  may  raise  the  interest  rate  on  other 
loans  to  cover  the  loss,  since  they  are  all  recallable  on  a  few 
weeks'  notice;  or,  it  may  charge  a  little  more  for  its  bank- 
ing services  or  raise  the  selling  price  of  supplies.  This  would 
not  materially  affect  members,  because  supplies  are  bought 
and  sold  at  wholesale  and  services  are  rendered  without  charge 
or  at  a  lower  figure  than  that  of  non-cooperative  institutions. 
Thus  step  after  step  may  be  taken  before  the  unlimited  lia- 
bility is  reached,  and  it  is  protected  from  creditors  until  the 
society  has  exhausted  all  its  profits  and  means  of  increasing 
its  profits  and  all  its  capital,  reserve  and  foundation  fund. 
Such  an  eventuality  is  highly  improbable,  because  specula- 
tion is  forbidden  and  offers  no  temptation  to  oiEcials  who 
cannot  receive  any  gain  and  must  suffer  along  with  the  other 
members  for  any  losses  resulting  from  a  risky  transaction, 
while  if  mismanagement  should  appear  it  could  not  long 
continue,  since  the  members  have  the  right  of  summary  dis- 
missal of  offending  of5cials  and  also  of  dissolving  the  society 
if  they  find  it  in  failing  circumstances  and  winding  up  its 
affairs. 

The  Eaiffeisen  society  is  a  perfect  organ  for  facilitating 
the  flow  of  capital  and  cheapening  credit  for  agriculture. 
The  record  of  the  thousands  of  these  little  banis  in  Germany 
of  never  having  lost  a  cent  belonging  to  the  millions  of  peo- 
ple who  have  dealt  with  them  during  the  past  50  years  is 
unparalleled  in  the  history  of  finance.  It  is  so  marvelous  as 
to  be  unbelievable  by  those  not  acquainted  with  the  facts. 
The  hundreds  of  millions  of  dollars  which  they  put  in  circu- 
lation during  that  period  rescued  the  German  farmers  from 
usury,  poverty  and  apathetic  despair,  made  them  their  own 
bankers,  merchants  and  instructors,  raised  them  in  the  scale 
of  life,  and  put  them  in  the  way  of  helping  themselves  and 
their  neighbors.  Eaiffeisen  made  the  dollar  beneficent  with- 
out interfering  with  its  usefulness.     He  was  the  first  man 


THE   KAIFFEISEN    SYSTEM  295 

to  understand  the  credit  value  of  farmers  and  to  utilize  it  for 
their  financial  needs.  The  Schulze-Delitzsch  credit  societies 
require  their  large  shares  to  be  paid  in  small  weekly  or 
monthly  instalments  ia  order  to  enforce  saving  and  they 
strengthen  the  habit  of  thrift  thus  formed  by  arousing  a 
cupidity  for  big  dividends;  consequently  the  interest  rate 
on  their  loans  is  usually  as  high  as  that  charged  by  ordinary 
banks.  But  Eaiffeisen  would  not  tolerate  dividends  because 
they  benefited  the  more  prosperous  members  at  the  expense  of 
the  borrowers  and  interfered  with  the  development  of  a  true 
spirit  of  mutuality  within  the  society.  As  a  result  of  this 
absence  of  the  spirit  of  lucre,  fratemi^  reigns  supreme  in  his 
societies  and  the  interest  rate  on  loans  is  often  as  low  as 
that  on  the  safest  kind  of  securities.  Eaiffeisen  was  opposed 
to  a  capital  stock  because  he  thought  that  the  best  place  for 
farmers  to  put  their  savings  was  in  the  land,  and  he  con- 
sidered that  periodical  payments  on  long-time  loans  was  as  an 
effective  way  to  encourage  thrift  as  periodical  payments  on 
shares. 

Eaiffeisen  was  also  the  first  man  to  realize  that  coopera- 
tion could  not  attain  its  fidl  usefulness  for  agriculture  with- 
out combination,  and  that  there  had  to  be  cooperation  among 
the  cooperative  societies  as  close  as  that  among  the  individual 
members.  For  this  reason  he  established  his  branch  banks 
and  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank,  his  unions  and  sub- 
unions,  and  over  all  the  Federation,  to  weld  the  local  units 
together  in  a  great  national  economic  force  for  their  mutual 
protection  and  assistance,  preserve  them  in  their  harmonious 
relations,  and  help  the  farmers  to  live  and  work  according 
to  the  principles  which  he  laid  down  of  brotherly  love  and 
Christian  charity.  The  firm  belief  that  Eaiffeisen  had  in  the 
lasting  value  of  these  principles  and  his  other  ideas,  and  his 
intention  to  keep  them  alive  forever  are  shown  by  his  crea- 
tion of  indivisible  reserves,  which  having  accumulated  in  the 
societies  for  nearly  two  generations,  now  amount  to  some 
millions  of  doUars  and  serve  as  a  permanent  fund  donated 
to  the  agricultural  public  for  carrying  on  and  perpetuating 
his  system  in  Germany. 


CHAPTER   XXIII 

GEEMAN  SYSTEMS  AT  PRESENT 

Listributive  Societies  of  William  Haas. — Imperial  Federation  of 
Agricultural  Cooperative  Societies  and  the  Eaiffeisen  General 
Federation. — ^Unions,  or  Local  Cooperative  Associations. — State 
Aid. — ^Ineome  and  Audit  of  the  Unions. — Examples  of  Failures 
among  Societies  and  Banks. — Cooperative  Banks  for  Agricul- 
tural Systems. — ^Prussian  Central  Cooperative  Bank.  Small 
Credit  Societies  at  Base  of  Whole  System. — Their  Organiza- 
tion, Rules,  and  Liabilities. — Statistics. 

The  cooperative  societies  attached  to  the  federations  of 
Schiilze-Delitzsch  and  Eaiffeisen  were  not  the  only  ones  estab- 
lished ia  Germany  during  their  lives.  The  work  of  these 
founders  of  cooperation  created  a  movement  which  advanced 
beyond  their  personal  control,  and  in  a  number  of  the  German 
states  their  priaciples  were  used  or  adapted  for  forming 
many  societies  for  various  cooperative  purposes,  which  had 
been  organized  in  groups  by  imitators  who  did  not  recog- 
nize their  leadership. 

The  most  prominent  of  these  new  men  was  William  Haas, 
who  was  bom  at  Darmstadt  in  1839  and  for  40  years  played 
an  important  part  in  agricultural  cooperation  before  his  death 
in  1913.  Haas'  activities  began  ia  1872  by  founding  an  agri- 
cultural distributive  society  at  Friedberg  in  Hesse.  The  dis- 
tributive, next  to  the  credit,  societies  were  the  earliest  form 
which  cooperation  assumed  in  Germany  and  they  had  a  rapid 
development  in  Hesse.  Their  objects  were  to  trade  in  cattle 
and  to  make  collective  purchases  of  feed,  fertilizer  and  seed 
for  sale  to  members,  but  they  were  handicapped  by  the  fact 
that  each  acted  independently  of  the  others.  Haas  conceived 
the  plan  of  combining  all  the  societies  in  the  Grand  Duchy 

296 


GERMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PEESENT  297 

into  a  union.  This  was  done  in  IST'S  and  Haas  was  elected 
president.  The  union  opened  its  doors  to  some  other  Hessian 
agricultural  cooperative  societies  in  1890,  and  at  the  same 
time,  ceasing  to  act  as  the  business  agent  of  its  adherents, 
it  formed  a  central  society  for  collective  purchase  and  lim- 
ited its  own  functions  to  auditing,  inspecting  and  represent- 
ing the  general  interests  of  the  societies.  The  method  adopted 
in  Hesse  was  followed  in  adjoining  provinces,  and  in  1883 
Haas  realized  his  idea  of  uniting  the  provincial  unions  into 
an  organization  which  later  on  took  the  name  of  the  Imperial 
Federation  of  Agricultural  Cooperative  Societies,  with  him- 
self as  director-general.  Thenceforth  Haas  became  the 
strongest  and  most  conspicuous  figure  in  cooperation  in  Ger- 
many, for  Schulze-Delitzsch  had  died  and  Eaifleisen  was 
reaching  the  end  of  his  days. 

The  societies  belonging  to  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  federa- 
tion, although  they  have  many  members  who  are  farmers, 
are  all  located  in  cities  and  have  a  distinctly  urban  character. 
Haas  and  Eaifleisen  were  interested  in  agriculture  alone,  but 
Haas  opposed  the  mixing  of  religion  and  business  and  also 
the  centralization  which  Eaiffeisen  favored.  Moreover,  he 
stood  neutral  as  regards  share  capital  and  unlimited  liability, 
and  used  what  seemed  to  him  good  of  both  the  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  and  Eaiffeisen  systems  wherever  it  seemed  desirable 
or  expedient  to  do  so.  During  its  first  five  years  his  Imperial 
Federation  acted  only  as  the  center  for  cooperative  purchas- 
ing societies  and  dairies,  but  after  EaifEeisen's  death  in  1888 
it  decided  to  admit  credit  societies  and  then  a  bitter  rivalry 
and  struggle  for  mastery  ensued.  The  Imperial  Federation 
won  in  1905  when  all  the  Eaiffeisen  societies  went  over  to  it, 
retaining,  however,  their  membership  in  the  General  Fed- 
eration for  guidance,  instruction  and  the  preservation  of  the 
principles  of  their  founder.  This  arrangement  proved  un- 
satisfactory and  was  dissolved  on  May  30,  1913 ;  hence  there 
are  now  two  systems  of  agricultural  cooperation  in  Germany, 
the  duality  of  which  often  leads  to  useless  duplication  of 
work. 

The  Imperial  Federation  has  maintained  its  dominance  in 


298  KTJEAL    CEEDITS 

spite  of  the  secession  and  the  great  majority  of  the  rural  co- 
operative societies  are  allied  with  it.  Its  headquarters  are  at 
Darmstadt,  and  it  embraces  the  whole  of  Germany  and  the 
German  protectorates.  Membership  is  open  to  all  unions  of 
agricultural  societies,  their  central  organizations,  and  indi- 
vidual associations  in  the  protectorates  and  foreign  lands.  Its 
administration  is  composed  of  three  parts.  The  first  is  the 
director-general  and  two  vice-presidents  elected  for  five  years 
at  the  annual  convention  of  its  adherents,  the  second  is  the 
general  committee,  composed  of  the  director-general,  the 
managers  of  the  unions,  and  six  representatives  of  the  provin- 
cial cooperative  banks  and  trading  associations  and  the  na- 
tional bank  and  institutions  of  the  Federation,  which  are 
empowered  to  decide  upon  matters  of  importance  in  case  of 
urgency,  prepare  resolutions  and  carry  out  those  that  are 
adopted  at  the  annual  convention,  pass  upon  the  accounts 
and  applications  for  membership,  and  fix  the  budget  and  the 
contributions  of  members;  the  third  is  an  executive  council 
consisting  of  the  director-general,  vice-presidents  and  seven 
persons  selected  from  the  general  committee  for  five  years, 
whose  duties  are  to  give  advice  to  officials,  prepare  the  agenda 
for  the  annual  convention,  examine  the  accounts,  draw  up 
the  annual  report  and  all  resolutions  and  proposals  to  be 
submitted  to  the  general  committee,  and  decide  on  the  expul- 
sion of  adhering  societies.  In  addition  there  are  various  spe- 
cial committees  formed  for  particular  groups  of  societies. 

Besides  holding  the  annual  convention,  the  activities  of 
the  Imperial  Federation  include  the  publishing  of  a  yearbook, 
an  official  organ  known  as  the  Agricultural  Cooperative  Press, 
issued  twice  a  month  for  free  distribution  to  its  adherents, 
and  a  monthly  bulletin  which  is  sent  to  all  newspapers  and 
periodicals  on  its  exchange  list.  It  publishes  also  books  and 
pamphlets  on  agricultural  and  cooperative  subjects.  It  con- 
ducts a  school  to  train  young  men  to  be  officers  in  the  coop- 
erative associations  and  strives  to  secure  positions  for  them 
after  graduation.  It  holds  lecture  courses  and  awards  prizes 
to  stimulate  efficiency,  gives  liberal  salaries,  grants  pensions  to 
widows  and  orphans  of  officers,  and  owns  two  hotels  opened 


GEEMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PRESENT  299 

during  the  summer  for  officers  and  their  families  at  reason- 
able rates.  It  retains  a  lawyer  and  a  corps  of  experts  for 
constructing  granaries  and  electrical  plants  and  for  purchas- 
ing chemical  fertilizers,  and  has  made  contracts  for  preferen- 
tial rates  of  insurance  against  loss  or  theft  of  money  and 
valuables  sent  by  mail;  and  finally  it  audits  the  accounts  of 
the  unions  and  institutions  directly  belonging  to  it. 

The  General  Federation  has  its  headquarters  at  Berlin. 
Membership  is  open  to  auditing  unions,  credit  societies  and 
societies  for  other  cooperative  purposes,  central  banks  and 
central  associations  which  have  been  organized  upon  and  fol- 
low the  principles  of  EaifEeisen.  Its  administration  consists 
of  a  director-general  and  a  deputy;  a  general  committee  com- 
posed of  these  officials,  the  managers  of  the  imions,  and  the 
directors  of  the  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank ;  and  a  board 
of  supervision  identical  with  the  board  of  supervision  of 
that  bank.  Its  activities  are  similar  to  those  of  the  Imperial 
Federation  and  it  has  all  the  objects  and  purposes  of  the 
latter,  with  the  addition  that  it  strives  to  promote  the  moral, 
intellectual  and  material  welfare  of  farmers  by  encouraging 
the  practice  of  Christianity. 

Since  the  enactment  of  the  law  of  1889  giving  to  the 
unions  the  power  to  act  as  ofBcial  auditors,  and  especially 
since  the  decentralization  of  the  systems  which  was  carried 
into  complete  effect  in  1905,  the  unions  or  groups  of  local 
cooperative  associations  have  become  the  most  important  fac- 
tors in  the  two  rural  federations  for  extending  cooperation 
and  coordinating  the  local  societies  into  systems.  The  union 
was  the  first  form  of  combination.  The  federations,  in  fact, 
started  as  unions  and  attained  their  present  position  by  en- 
larging their  scope  and  areas.  The  unions  are  organized  by 
provinces  in  Prussia  and  generally  by  states  in  the  rest  of 
Germany,  and  they  comprise  over  92  per  cent  of  all  the  local 
societies.  There  are  some  unions  organized  for  special  classes 
of  societies,  such  as  dairy  associations.  Formerly  most  of 
the  unions  did  collective  buying  and  selling  for  members 
but  now  all  except  two  have  abandoned  this  business  and 
serve  in  their  respective  areas  as  the  federations  serve  through- 


300  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

out  the  nation.  Three  unions  in  Wiirttemberg,  Baden  and 
Treves  are  so  large  as  to  rival  the  federations,  and  they  have 
refused  to  attach  themselves  to  either  of  the  systems.  The 
largest  union  in  a  federation  is  that  of  Bavaria,  with  2,814 
societies,  and  the  smallest  is  that  of  Alsace-Lorraine,  with 
23  societies.  Between  these  extremes  the  number  varies  from 
38  up  to  1,417,  with  an  average  of  500.  The  sub-unions  have 
ten  to  thirty  societies.  The  administration  of  the  union  is  the 
triple  arrangement  familiar  in  all  cooperative  organizations, 
and  consists  of  an  executive  head  and  deputies,  a  committee 
of  management,  and  a  board  of  directors  or  supervisors, 
elected  at  an  annual  meeting  of  the  adhering  societies,  in 
which  each  society  has  only  one  vote.  Thus  the  union  has 
its  own  oflBcers,  funds  and  sources  of  income ;  this  assures  its 
independence  and  the  complete  decentralization  which  Haas 
fought  for  so  long. 

The  older  unions  were  chartered  by  their  own  provinces 
or  states  but  the  newer  ones  were  generally  organized  under 
the  Imperial  laws  for  non-profit-making  associations.  Nearly 
every  province  gives  state  aid  of  some  sort.  Alsace-Lor- 
raine grants  $1,342  to  the  unions  annually  and  has  opened 
an  account  with  them  for  $338,000  at  four  per  cent.  In 
Brandenburg  the  union  gets  $1,520  a  year.  In  Baden  the 
unions  receive  $4,563  annually,  while  the  local  societies  are 
allowed  a  drawing  account  up  to  $507,000  at  three  per  cent 
and  public  moneys  are  deposited  with  the  credit  societies.  In 
Bavaria  nearly  $169,000  was  given  for  rural  cooperation  be- 
tween 1897  and  1904,  and  since  the  latter  date  the  annual 
allowance  has  been  maintained.  East  Prussia  gives  annually 
$810;  Hanover,  $1,352;  Hesse,  $1,690;  Hesse-Cassel,  $1,204; 
Hesse-Kassau,  $845;  Posen,  $3,535;  the  Ehine  Province, 
$1,521;  Prussian  Saxony,  $5,427;  Silesia,  $2,366  at  least; 
Schleswig-Holstein  and  Westphalia,  $1,521;  West  Prussia, 
$400 ;  and  Saxony,  $4,056 ;  while  Westphalia  pays  the  salary 
of  the  managing  director  of  the  union.  Small  sums  ranging 
from  $12  to  $50  also  are  given  to  new  local  societies  by 
Brandenburg,  Bast  Prussia,  Hanover,  Hesse-Cassel,  Pom- 
erania,  Posen,  West  Prussia  and  Wiirttemberg.     Some  of  the 


GEEMA]!T   SYSTEMS   AT   PEESENT         301 

provinces  pay  part  of  the  cost  of  training  cooperative  officers. 

The  state  donations  emimerated  comprise  loans  or-  the  ex- 
tension of  credit  at  low  interest  rates  to  the  hanks  and  direct 
grants  of  money  for  education,  propaganda  and  organization 
work  to  the  unions.  They  do  not  includCj  however,  all  the 
state  aid  given  in  Germany  to  cooperation.  Other  state  ap- 
propriations have  been  made,  while  the  chambers  of  agri- 
cnltnre  have  been  exceedingly  liberal  and  active  in  its  behalf. 
These  are  semi-pnblic  bodies  which  Prussia  and  other  German 
states  have  required  to  be  established  by  law.  Their  object 
is  the  care  of  all  matters  pertaining  to  forestry  and  agricul- 
ture, the  improvement  of  the  technical  and  economic  educa- 
tion of  the  farmers,  and  the  advancement  of  cooperation. 
Money  for  the  expenses  and  projects  of  the  chambers  of  agri- 
culture is  raised  by  taxing  farms  within  their  jurisdiction 
up  to  an  amount  not  exceeding  one-half  of  one  per  cent  of 
the  regular  land  tax.  Some  provinces  also  make  special  ap- 
propriations for  them.  Membership  is  open,  among  others, 
to  resident  persons  making  their  living  by  farming  and  to 
representatives  of  cooperative  associations.  Members  must  be 
elected  by  the  county  councils  and  hold  office  for  six  years. 
The  number  of  members  varies  from  32  to  124  for  each 
chamber.  The  German  Council  of  Agriculture,  composed  of 
75  delegates  from  the  chambers  of  agriculture,  serves  as  the 
chief  adviser  of  the  Government  on  all  agricultural  aflfairs. 

Generally  speaking,  state  aid  is  favored  by  the  rural  and 
opposed  by  the  urban  societies.  It  is  not  extended  as  much 
as  formerly  but  is  stiU  considerable,  and  the  aggregate  of 
the  sums  granted  since  Germany  changed  from  a  hostile  to  a 
friendly  attitude  towards  cooperation  is  enormous.  Although 
the  first  cooperative  convention  called  by  Schulze-Delitzsch 
in  1859  was  not  allowed  to  be  held  in  Saxony,  yet  in  1865 
Prussia  appointed  a  commission  to  devise  ways  and  means  for 
promoting  cooperation  among  factory  workers.  Some  years 
later  the  King  of  Prussia  gave  personal  gifts  to  Eaiffeisen 
and  provided  also  for  establishing  cooperative  societies  among 
striking  SHesian  weavers  to  prevent  them  from  drifting  into 
socialism.     Since  1895  Prussia  has  advanced  hundreds  of 


302  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

thousands  of  dollars  to  its  central  cooperative  banking  insti- 
tution and  about  $1,650,000  to  cooperative  granaries  and 
cattle-seUing  societies.  During  the  lasi  30  years  the  German 
Government  has  had  a  marked  predilection  for  agricultural 
cooperation  and  has  encouraged  its  development  through 
miaisters  of  the  Imperial  Cabinet,  provincial  governors,  local 
officials,  the  chambers  of  agriculture,  and  public  school 
teachers. 

But  state  aid  and  governmental  encouragement  have  never 
been  more  than  partial  and  incidental  means  of  support.    The 
chief  source  of  income  of  the  unions  is  contributions  from  the 
local  societies  and  provincial  cooperative  banks  and  trading 
societies  and  in  ease  of  need  from  the  federations.  The  method 
of  assessment  is  not  uniform.    Usually,  however,  annual  dues 
are  charged  and  a  percentage  of  the  turnover  of  business  is 
exacted,  while  each  society  must  pay  the  actual  expense  in- 
curred or  stated  amounts  for  all  services  rendered  it  and  the 
cost  or  fixed  price  of  articles  which  it  is  bound  to  buy  from 
the  union,  such  as  account  books,  textbooks,  models,  forms, 
office  supplies,  periodicals  and  publications.     Most  of  the 
unions  receive  also  from  the  trading  societies  their  net  profits 
remaining  after  a  moderate  dividend  has  been  paid  on  shares 
and  a  levy  set  aside  for  the  reserve.    In  this  way  the  unions 
obtain  all  the  money  they  need  for  themselves  and  for  main- 
taining the  federations.    It  must  be  borne  in  mind  that,  with 
several  exceptions,  the  unions  generally  have  nothing  to  do 
whatever  with  financial  or  business  transactions  but  confine 
their  activities  to  propaganda,  educational  and  organization 
work,  safeguarding  and  furtheriug  the  general  interests  of 
the  societies  and  their  systems,  and  auditing  the  societies  at 
regular  intervals.    The  latter  has  become  the  most  important 
duty  of  the  unions  since  the  law  of  1889  requires  all  regis- 
tered cooperative  societies  to  submit  to  an  audit. 

The  compulsory  outside  audit,  an  audit  by  someone 
neither  an  officer  nor  member  of  the  society,  has  been  the 
greatest  factor  in  standardizing  business  methods,  enforcing 
conformity  to  statutory  and  conventional  requirements,  and 
giving  strength  and  public  confidence  to  cooperation  in  Ger- 


GERMAN    SYSTEMS   AT   PRESENT         303 

many.  Sehulze-Delitzsch  introduced  it  before  1868,  Raiffei- 
sen  adopted  it  in  1880,  and  Haas  had  insisted  upon  it  from 
the  start,  so  it  was  self-imposed  before  the  law  made  it  ob- 
ligatory. The  GoTFemment  debated  a  long  time  whether  or 
not  to  take  the  audit  upon  itself,  but  realizing  the  difficul- 
ties and  expense  of  examining  by  public  employees  the  petty 
and  voluminous  affairs  of  thousands  of  small  societies,  it 
decided  to  leave  the  auditing  to  their  unions,  or  if  they  were 
attached  to  no  union,  to  persons  appointed  by  the  courts. 
The  law  provides  that  this  audit  must  be  made  every  second 
year,  and  must  cover  an  inspection  of  the  books,  accounts, 
cash,  securities  and  goods.  Nearly  all  the  unions  make  it 
annually,  either  upon  notice  or  as  a  surprise,  and  besides 
examining  the  assets  and  liabilities  minutely,  they  investigate 
the  acts  and  capacity  of  officers,  see  whether  the  laws  and 
by-laws  have  been  observed,  inspect  and  supervise  the  entire 
situation  of  the  local  societies,  and  make  what  recommenda- 
tions they  deem  fit.  The  only  way  in  which  they  can  enforce 
these  recommendations,  however,  is  by  expelling  the  delin- 
quent society  from  the  xmion  or  by  suggesting  that  the 
banks  refuse  it  credit. 

In  January,  1913,  the  Imperial  Federation  included  41 
tinions  with  71  provincial  associations  and  20,780  local  so- 
cieties, of  which  13,736  were  credit  societies.  The  total  num- 
ber of  individual  members  exceeded  2,000,000.  It  had  also 
four  central  institutions  and  the  German  Wine  Growers'  So- 
ciety of  Palestine.  But  in  May  of  that  year,  the  General 
Federation  seceded  and  took  away  its  13  unions  with  their 
4,626  local  credit  societies,  seven  provincial  trading  associa- 
tions and  eight  provincial  banks,  and  its  Central  Agricul- 
tural Loan  Bank,  with  approximately  450,000  individual 
members.  The  central  institutions  remaining  were  the  Im- 
perial Cooperative  Bank,  a  joint-stock  company;  the  Cattle 
Selling  Society,  a  limited-liability  association ;  and  the  Potash 
Purchasing  Company,  also  a  limited-liability  concern.  The 
shares  in  these  institutions  were  owned  mainly  by  the  pro- 
vincial associations.  All  these  associations,  whether  for  bank- 
ing or  business,  are  likewise  organized  on  the  limited-liability 


304  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

plan,  and  their  shares  are  owned  by  the  local  societies,  some 
of  which  have  Limited  and  others  nnlimited  liability.  All  the 
provincial  associations  of  the  Eaiffeisen  federation  have  been 
organized  in  the  same  way  and  its  Central  Agricultural  Loan 
Bank  is  a  joint-stock  company.  Hence  neither  of  the  sys- 
tems has  a  pure  form  of  cooperative  organization  at  the  top, 
whUe  imlimited  liability  does  not  appear  anywhere  except 
among  the  basic  units.  The  farmers  individually  have  no 
ownership  or  power  of  control  in  this  great  superstructure 
which  has  been  erected  upon  them  and  with  their  money, 
while'  some  of  the  provincial  associations  and  central  insti- 
tutions are  so  large  that  the  local  societies,  which  have  sup- 
plied the  funds  for  their  capital,  take  no  part  or  interest 
in  their  management.  While  the  ofiBcers  have  been  in  the 
main  honest,  faithful  and  capable,  instances  of  bad  judg- 
ment, incompetence  and  even  corruption  have  occurred  with 
serious  consequences. 

The  grain-selling  associations  of  Strassburg  failed  in 
1904,  the  Central  Society  of  German  Wine  Growers  in  1905, 
and  the  Bavarian  Hop  Growers'  Society  in  1909.  The  Co- 
operative Tobacco  Sales  Society  of  the  Pfalz  and  the  grain- 
seUing  societies  of  Ludwigshafen  met  with  financial  reverses 
in  1911.  These  were  all  very  large  concerns  formed  by 
shares  subscribed  by  the  Eaiffeisen  local  societies.  The  losses 
reached  into  the  millions.  In  fact,  the  Central  Agricultural 
Loan  Bank  and  many  local  credit  societies  faced  ruin  be- 
cause of  the  inability  of  the  sales  associations  to  pay  back 
money  which  had  been  borrowed,  and  were  saved  only  by  the 
bonding  of  the  debt  to  the  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank 
and  in  one  case  through  the  assistance  of  the  state.  The 
Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  asked  each  of  the  local  credit 
societies  to  pay  $750  to  be  returned  in  instalments  for  15 
years.  A  few  of  the  Bavarian  and  Posen  societies  refused, 
but  3,000  societies  complied  with  the  request  and  thus  the 
matter  was  adjusted. 

Bad  records  have  been  made  also  within  the  Imperial 
Federation.  The  loan  and  savings  society  of  the  peasants  and 
tradespeople  of  Meder-Modau,  near  Darmstadt,  was  declared 


GEEMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PEESENT  305 

insolvent  in  December,  1911.  Its  deficit  amounted  to  aronnd 
$400,000.  Most  of  the  members  were  poor,  with  assets  rang- 
ing from  $500  down  to  nothing.  One,  however,  was  worth 
$50,000  and  he  had  to  txirn  all  of  this  fortune  over  to  the 
creditors.  His  only  hope  of  recovery  lies  in  the  notes  of  equal 
amount  which  the  court  compelled  the  other  members  to 
execute  in  his  favor.  The  causes  of  this  failure  were  exces- 
sive ambition  and  a  too  extensive  territory.  Unlimited  lia- 
bility is  safe  only  where  operations  are  restricted  to  a  very 
limited  area.  The  Nieder-Modau  credit  society  attracted  de- 
posits from  aU  over  the  province  by  offering  high  interest 
rates,  and  more  than  $750,000  poured  in  within  a  few  months. 
This  amount  was  far  in  excess  of  the  needs  of  members,  and 
the  bank  made  loans  to  outsiders.  Some  of  the  money  was 
invested  in  first  and  second  mortgages  on  building  lots  and 
in  speculative  ventures  in  urban  real  estate.  After  the  crash 
the  investigation  showed  that  the  managers,  directors  and 
supervisors  had  been  remiss  in  their  duties  and  that  the 
secretary  had  been  guilty  of  speculations.  One  was  sen- 
tenced and  imprisoned  for  forgery. 

In  March,  1913,  the  Central  Agricultural  Cooperative 
Bank  of  the  union  at  Darmstadt  had  to  undergo  liquidation, 
owing  to  the  locking  up  of  $2,125,000  in  the  Cooperative 
Bank  of  Prankfort-on-the-Main  and  to  the  default  of  $2,250,- 
000  advanced  to  the  Administration  and  Sales  Cooperative 
Society.  The  latter  association  was  formed  a  few  years  ago 
to  administer  and  sell  the  real  estate  in  which  various  so- 
cieties had  imwisely  invested  their  deposits  and  surpluses 
for  which  they  had  no  immediate  use.  The  Frankfort-on- 
the-Main  bank  was  founded  in  1902  to  act  as  a  central  insti- 
tution for  a  number  of  union  banks  and  purchasing  asso- 
ciations. Deviating  from  true  banking  methods,  it  con- 
tracted an  alliance  with  a  mismanaged  land  mortgage  com- 
pany, was  tempted  by  the  chance  of  making  big  profits  into 
risky  specxdations  in  land  and  mines,  and  thus  went  to  the 
wall.  A  panic  ensued  among  the  adhering  members  of  the 
Central  Agricultural  Cooperative  Bank  of  Darmstadt  when 
they  learned  of  its  connections  vsdth  these  bankrupt  concerns. 


306  ETJEAL    CREDITS 

and  they  began  to  withdraw  deposits  and  accounts  and  can- 
cel their  memberships,  but  too  late  to  avoid  the  consequences 
of  the  failure.  Their  losses  exceeded  $3,750,000,  while  other 
societies  have  become  so  involved  with  them  that  a  dan- 
gerous crisis  has  arisen  in  the  agricultural  cooperative  credit 
societies  of  the  Grand  Duchy  of  Hesse,  due  to  the  fact  that 
several  of  the  banks  grew  large  too  rapidly,  became  over- 
loaded with  idle  funds  and  got  tangled  up  with  real-estate 
transactions. 

The  recent  disasters  have  had  a  very  bad  moral  as  well 
as  material  effect  and  illustrate  the  danger  of  pyramiding  a 
large  institution  upon  underlying  societies.  Nevertheless,  the 
German  agricultural  cooperative  systems  have  been  created 
by  thus  building  provincial  or  regional  and  national  organi- 
zations upon  the  local  units,  and  they  have  been  able  to  with- 
stand these  severe  shocks  because  they  are  not  artificial  but 
with  a  few  exceptions  are  the  result  of  slow,  cumulative 
growth  under  leaders  who  have  been  self-denying,  honest 
and  public-spirited.  The  experience  in  Germany,  however, 
has  led  to  the  belief  that  if  agricultural  cooperative  systems 
must  have  national  financial  institutions,  they  should  not  be 
banking  organizations  to  handle  funds  but  rather  federal 
boards  to  direct  and  regulate  their  flow.  This  was  Schulze- 
Delitzsch's  original  plan,  as  shown  by  the  bureau  of  cor- 
respondence and  exchange  which  he  established. 

The  mainstay  and  base  of  these  systems  are  their  banks. 
In  the  Eaifleisen  federation  are  the  Central  Agricultural  Loan 
Bank,  a  banking  and  trading  concern  with  12  branches,  the 
shares  of  which  are  owned  by  the  local  credit  societies,  and 
eight  provincial  banks  formed  for  trading  societies.  The 
Imperial  Federation  has  the  Imperial  Cooperative  Bank,  the 
shares  of  which  are  owned  by  provincial  trading  associations, 
and  36  provincial  banks  for  its  local  societies.  Of  the  three 
independent  groups  of  rural  societies,  Wiirttemberg  and 
Treves  have  their  own  provincial  banks,  while  Baden  has  ar- 
ranged with  a  mortgage  company  to  act  as  its  banker.  The 
provincial  banks  are  usually  called  union  or  central  banks; 
names  which  describe  them  more  accurately  because  the  banks 


GERMAN    SYSTEMS   AT   PRESENT         307 

are  always  attached  to  unions  wMle  their  area  of  operations 
is  not  everywhere  coterminous  with  political  divisions.  The 
provincial,  union  or  central  banks  are  all  organized  as  coop- 
erative associations  with  limited  liability  and  have  the  cus- 
tomary committees  of  management  and  boards  of  supervision. 
Membership  in  a  bank  is  open  to  all  registered  cooperative 
societies  irrespective  of  kind  or  purpose  belonging  to  its  sys- 
tem within  its  area,  to  its  own  officers  and  resident  persons, 
such  as  wealthy  farmers  or  large  landovmers,  although  they 
may  have  no  need  for  loans,  but  they  are  usually  very  few; 
and  to  benevolent  institutions,  chambers  of  agriculture  and 
agricultural  associations.  The  average  number  of  members 
in  a  union  bank  is  500.  The  value  of  the  share  runs  from 
about  $3.50  up  to  $360,  and  it  is  made  as  large  as  possible 
so  as  to  increase  the  capital.  In  some  cases  the  share  may  be 
paid  in  fixed  instalments  extending  over  two  years  but  usually 
it  must  be  paid  in  full  upon  subscription.  A  member  may 
hold  a  number  of  shares  but  according  to  law  a  new  share 
may  not  be  taken  out  until  shares  previously  subscribed  for 
have  been  paid  up.  The  liability  assumed  is  some  multiple 
of  the  face  value  of  the  share.  As  a  rule  it  is  made  high 
when  the  share  is  small  in  order  to  strengthen  the  credit 
standing  of  the  bank,  but  the  tendency  is  to  make  it  ten 
times  the  value  of  the  share.  Whenever  the  debts  of  a  xmion 
bank  exceed  one-fourth  the  aggregate  liability  of  members, 
the  law  requires  it  to  be  placed  in  bankruptcy.  ,  i 

The  working  capital  of  the  central  or  union  banks  con- 
sists of  the  amounts  paid  in  on  shares,  deposits  from  all  per- 
sons and  their  credit  at  their  national  banks.  In  accordance 
with  the  usual  cooperative  rule  the  shareholding  members 
must  transact  all  their  banking  business  through  the  bank  and 
employ  its  services  for  buying  stocks  and  bonds  for  investment. 
An  aiiering  society's  credit  is  based  on  the  number  of  shares 
held  or  paid  for.  This  is  called  the  normal  credit  and  the 
society  is  allowed  to  draw  on  the  bank  up  to  the  maximum  as 
a  matter  of  course  without  security.  If  the  society  needs 
credit  above  the  normal  limit,  the  application  must  be  passed 
on  by  the  board  of  supervision  and  security  may  be  exacted. 


308  EimAL   CEEDITS 

In  the  branches  of  the  Eaiffeisen  Central  Agricultural  Loan 
Bank  a  different  method  is  pursued.  The  local  societies,  it 
•will  be  remembered,  are  directly  connected  with  it  and  are 
all  of  the  unlimited-liability  type.  The  local  societies  send 
to  the  branches  every  year  an  official  statement  showing  the 
value  of  the  collective  assets  of  individual  members  and  from 
these  statements  the  bank  determines  the  extent  of  the  credit 
which  may  be  accorded  to  the  society.  In  states  where  there 
is  a  property  tax,  ten  per  cent  of  the  official  value  of  the  mem- 
bers' combined  property  may  be  allowed.  Where  there  is  no 
property  tax,  five  per  cent  of  the  value  as  determined  by  the 
society's  committee  of  management  is  the  limit.  The  local 
societies  use  their  credit  mainly  for  supplying  their  individual 
members  with  the  smaU  sums  they  require  for  planting  and 
marketing  their,  crops  and  this  is  why  credit  is  extended 
mostly  on  current  account.  But  the  central  banks  have  of 
course  the  power  of  granting  long-term  loans  for  large  defi- 
nite amounts,  and  many  of  them  accommodate  their  coop- 
erative associations  in  this  way  for  building  dairies,  ware- 
houses, electric  plants,  and  for  financing  various  projects. 
It  is  the  losses  and  the  permanent  sinking  of  their  funds 
through  this  part  of  the  business  which  have  frequently  got 
them  into  trouble.  The  union  banks  pay  from  3.5  to  4  per 
cent  on  deposits  and  charge  the  local  societies  from  4.5  to  5 
per  cent  for  loans  and  credit,  plus  a  commission  of  about  one- 
tenth  of  one  per  cent. 

The  business  done  is  enormous.  The  total  turnover  in 
■1911  for  34  central  or  union  banks  was  $1,489;770,300,  an 
average  of  about  $43,816,918  each,  and  it  was  nearly  all  done 
upon  deposits  of  affiliated  societies.  These  reached  a  total 
of  $304,145,440.  The  capital  and  reserves  of  each  bank  av- 
erage about  $334,467.20,  and  on  these  funds  all  the  banks 
earned  profits,  the  average  being  6.6  per  cent.  Dividends 
ranging  from  3.3  to  5  per  cent  were  declared  and  the  balance 
of  the  profits  was  used  largely  for  increasing  the  reserves. 
The  national  banks  of  the  systems  require  the  union  banks 
to  do  business  with  them  exclusively.  All  outside  dealings 
except  where  absolutely  necessary  are  barred  by  contract. 


GEEMAK   SYSTEMS   AT   PEESENT         309 

The  turnover  of  the  Imperial  Bank  in  1911  was  $146,404,800, 
of  the  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  in  1912,  $397,463,480. 
In  1912  the  4,636  members  of  this  latter  bank  owned  10,000 
shares  on  which  $2,298,480  had  been  paid  up  in  cash.  The 
•dividend  was  3.5  per  cent.  The  interest  rate  on  deposits 
fluctuated  between  3.5  and  4.4  per  cent,  and  on  advances  be- 
tween 4.4  and  4.75  per  cent,  to  which  was  added  one-tenth 
of  one  per  cent  for  commissions. 

As  already  pointed  out,  most  German  states  give  finan- 
cial assistance  to  the  unions  and  their  banks,  but  Prussia, 
the  birthplace  of  cooperation  on  the  Continent  and  the  largest 
province  of  the  Empire,  has  far  surpassed  all  others  in  this 
respect.  In  1895  it  created  the  Prussian  Central  Coopera- 
tive Bank  at  Berlin.  At  that  time  cooperation,  although  en- 
couraged by  the  King,  had  made  progress  only  in  small  iso- 
lated areas.  The  coordination  of  the  local  societies  into  the 
present  systems  was  in  evolution.  The  Central  Agricultural 
Loan  Bank  had  not  yet  attained  importance.  Commercial 
banks  were  ignorant  of  the  principles  of  cooperative  credit 
and  declined  to  consider  as  a  practical  security  the  collective 
guaranty  of  persons  whom  they  knew  to  be  individually 
weak;  moreover  they  had  all  the  opportunity  they  desired  for 
the  profitable  employment  of  their  funds  in  the  rapidly 
expanding  trade  and  commerce.  Thus  the  money  markets 
were  closed  to  the  cooperative  societies  and  they  lacked  the 
cash  to  make  necessary  loans  to  members  and  to  meet  -with- 
drawals of  deposits  during  the  busy  seasons.  It  was  to  re- 
lieve this  situation,  permanently  to  remove  the  cause  of  the 
trouble  and  to  encourage  the  development  of  cooperation  that 
the.  Kingdom  of  Prussia  decided  to  act.  The  express  design 
of  the  Prussian  Central  Cooperative  Bank  was  to  help  the 
middle  classes  in  town  and  country  by  the  promotion  of  co- 
operative credit  among  them.  It  is  a  pure  governmental  in- 
stitution and  its  capital  stock  of  $18,000,000  was  granted  by 
the.  Kingdom.  The  organic  act  allows  union  cooperative 
banks  to  participate  but  so  far  they  have  contributed  only 
$360,000.  The  bank  is  managed  by  a  president  and  four 
directors  appointed  for  life  by  the  King,  and  these  with  some 


310  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

200  other  officials  are  public  employees.  An  advisory  com- 
mittee of  30,  chosen  from  the  more  prominent  members  of 
cooperative  associations,  serves  as  a  medium  of  communica- 
tion with  the  latter  but  it  has  nothing  to  do  with  the  manage- 
ment. The  Bank  is  supervised  by  the  Minister  of  Finance 
who  vdth  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  directs  its  policy,  and 
its  accounts  are  examined  by  public  auditors  whose  report 
must  be  submitted  annually  to  Parliament  for  action.  Al- 
though created  for  Prussia  alone,  the  Bank  eventually  tried 
to  set  itself  up  as  the  financial  head  of  cooperation  through- 
out the  Empire  by  attaching  to  itself  the  national  banks 
of  the  systems,  both  of  which  are  located  within  the  Kingdom. 
It  cannot  deal  directly  with  local  societies.  Its  charter  allows 
it  to  reach  them  only  through  the  union,  central  and  other 
large  banks  of  the  systems.  In  addition  to  the  cooperative 
business  for  which  it  was  especially  founded,  it  may  grant 
loans  to  the  landschafts,  public  land  banks  and  public  sav- 
ings banks,  buy  and  sell  securities  on  commission  and  receive 
deposits.  The  Bank  determines  the  credit  value  of  a  coop- 
erative association  by  the  method  employed  by  the  union 
banks.  For  a  cooperative  joint-stock  company,  it  calculates 
the  credit  value  upon  the  net  assets  as  set  forth  in  its  annual 
statement.  But  the  usual  extent  of  credit  allowed  the  coop- 
erative customer  is  ten  times  its  paid-up  capital  and  reserves, 
with  an  extreme  limit  of  $1,200,000.  About  40  per  cent  of 
the  credit  actually  extended  is  on  current  account  and  the 
rest  by  discounting  bills  of  exchange.  The  Bank  does  not  lend 
on  mortgage.  In  1912  its  capital  stood  at  $18,240,000,  and 
its  reserve  at  $2,040,000;  its  total  turnover  of  business  was 
$4,080,000,000,  and  its  profits  were  $720,000.  One-fifth  of 
the  profits  went  into  the  reserves  as  required  by  law  and  a 
3.3  per  cent  dividend  was  declared.  It  accords  a  preferen- 
tial rate  to  customers  who  agree  to  deal  with  it  exclusively. 
The  average  rates  for  1911  were  3  and  3.5  per  cent  for  bal- 
ances and  loans  on  current  accoimt,  4.09  per  cent  on  bills, 
and  5.50  per  cent  on  collateral  security,  and  they  generally 
foUow  those  of  the  National  Bank  of  the  Empire. 

The  position  of  the  Prussian  Central  Cooperative  Bank 


GERMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PEESENT  311 

is  not  as  strong  with  cooperation  as  formerly.  In  1905  the 
Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  of  the  Eaiffeisen  federation 
joined  it,  being  forced  thereto  by  heavy  losses  and  the  in- 
creasing number  of  societies  whose  needs  it  was  unable  to 
supply.  This  relation  was  dissolved  in  1913  because  the  Prus- 
sian Cooperative  Central  Bank  tried  to  prevent  the  Loan 
Bank  from  dealing  directly  with  the  local  societies  and  thus 
compel  it  completely  to  change  its  organization  and  business 
methods.  Up  to  1898  the  Imperial  Federation  was  friendly 
with  the  Prussian  Central  Cooperative  Bank,  but  in.  that 
year  violent  objections  were  raised  to  its  credit  valuations  and 
interest  rates,  and  as  an  outcome  the  Imperial  Cooperative 
Bank  was  founded  ia  1903.  However,  nearly  all  the  imion 
banks  of  the  Imperial  Federation  are  now  allied  with  the 
Prussian  Central  Bank.  The  Schulze-Delitzsch  federation 
opposes  it  in  principle  because  of  the  state  aid  it  enjoys, 
but  there  are  more  vital  reasons  for  the  ill-will  which  it, 
has  engendered.  The  Prussian  Central  Cooperative  Bank 
is  inclined  to  treat  the  head  institutions  of  the  federations 
as  rivals  and  wishes  to  abolish  them  altogether,  while  they 
in  their  turn  resent  its  forcing  of  contracts  from  the  union 
banks  so  as  to  compel  them  to  deal  exclusively  with  it.  These 
head  institutions  consider  this  as  an  aggression  upon  their 
rights.  Moreover,  they  accuse  its  management  of  being  bu- 
reaucratic and  they  denounce  its  accumulation  of  a  big  re- 
serve as  diverting  money  from  the  farmers.  Above  all  they 
inveigh  against  this  ofiBciaUy  directed  public  institution  as  a 
device  of  the  state  to  place  the  entire  cooperative  system  under 
the  control  of  the  Government.  Thus  the  Prussian  Central 
Cooperative  Bank,  although  created  with  the  best  of  inten- 
tions, has  become  the  cause  of  jealousies  and  dissensions  in 
German  cooperation,  exemplifying  the  troubles  invariably 
encoimtered  by  the  state  in  aiding  a  movement  which  rests 
upon  self-help  and  thrives  best  by  private  initiative.  Never- 
theless, the  Bank  continues  to  grow  in  spite  of  its  critics 
and  enemies.  In  1913  it  had  for  customers  53  union  banks, 
of  which  31  were  rural,  comprising  10,893  cooperative  socie- 
ties and  1,090,000  individual  members.    The  31  urban  pro- 


313  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

vincial  banks  had  622  cooperative  societies  connected  with 
them,  with  194,000  individual  members.  It  did  business  also 
with  eight  landschafts,  six  public  land  banks,  917  public 
savings  banks,  and  795  other  concerns  and  persons. 

In  brief,  then,  the  rural  cooperative  organization  of  Ger- 
many is  this:  The  local  credit  societies  and  societies  for 
other  cooperative  purposes  are  grouped,  by  provinces  in  Prus- 
sia and  by  states  in  the  rest  of  the  Empire,  into  unions  of 
which  the  majority  belong  to  the  Imperial  Federation  and 
the  minority  to  the  EaifEeisen  General  Federation,  while  a 
few  are  independent.  The  three  unions  of  Wiirttemberg, 
Baden  and  Treves  act  as  their  own  federations.  Except  in 
the  Eaiffeisen  federation  the  unions  have  formed  for  and 
out  of  the  local  societies  thus  grouped,  union  banks,  union 
associations  for  collective  buying  of  farm  supplies  and  equip- 
ment and  collective  selling  of  farm  products  of  the  individual 
members,  and  in  some  cases  cooperative  creameries,  wine  cel- 
lars, electric  light  and  power  plants,  and  other  cooperative 
concerns.  The  Baden  union  uses  an  outside  mortgage  com- 
pany as  its  bank.  The  regional  or  union  institutions  have 
formed  national  bodies,  which  extend  their  operations  over 
the  entire  country,  for  the  purchase  and  sale  in  bulk  of  ma- 
chinery and  articles  obtained  first  hand  from  the  manufac- 
turers. The  credit  societies  of  the  Eaiffeisen  federation  take 
care  not  only  of  the  credit  needs  of  their  members  but  also 
buy  and  sell  equipment,  supplies  and  sometimes  the  products 
of  their  individual  members.  All  of  them  belong  to  the 
Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank.  Societies  not  having  credit 
purposes  cannot  belong  to  this  bank.  Originally  they  could 
not  deal  with  it,  so  eight  of  the  groups  in  the  Eaiffeisen  fed- 
eration formed  union  banks  of  their  own.  Now,  however, 
the  Central  Agricultural  Loan  Bank  accords  its  banking  fa- 
cilities to  all  societies  without  regard  to  their  purpose.  Fur- 
thermore it  is  closing  out  its  trading  business  and  turning 
it  over  to  union  or  regional  associations,  of  which  seven  have 
already  been  formed,  and  it  plans  eventually  to  restrict  its 
branches  to  banking  alone  and  have  them  serve  as  the  finan- 
cial centers  of  the  imions. 


GERMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PRESENT  313 

Topping  this  elaborate  organization  is  the  Prussian  Cen- 
tral Cooperative  Bank,  founded,  financed  and  managed  by 
the  state  and  offering  its  services  to  the  banks  of  all  the 
■unions  and  federations  that  will  accept  its  terms  and  con- 
ditions. Since  Prussia  embraces  over  64  per  cent  of  the  area 
and  66  per  cent  of  the  population  of  Germany,  this  bank 
domiaates  the  cooperative  organization  and  has  become  the 
chief  financial  head  of  all  except  the  banks  of  the  Raiffeisen 
federation,  which  has  severed  relations  with  it.  The  Prussian 
Central  Cooperative  Bank  is  inspected  and  supervised  by 
the  Prussian  Ministers  of  Finance  and  Agriculture  and  by 
Parliament.  The  other  national  banks  and  associations  and 
the  imion  banks  and  associations  are  audited  and  supervised 
by  the  federations,  and  the  local  societies  by  the  unions.  In 
this  way,  over  two  millions  of  the  ten  million  German  farm- 
ers are  leagued  in  mutual  support  through  which  they  exert 
a  tremendous  influence  in  reducing  interest  rates  and  the 
cost  of  production,  manufacture '  and  marketing  of  agricul- 
tural products  and  thereby  do  infinite  good  for  themselves 
and  consumers.  But  at  the  base  of  the  entire  organization 
are  the  credit  societies,  which  are  individually  so  small  that 
vast  numbers  transact  their  business  in  the  country  schools 
or  churches,  or  in  rooms  in  the  village  homes  or  farmhouses 
of  their  officials. 

These  local  units,  which  for  nearly  two  generations  have 
been  collecting  the  earnings  and  savings  of  members  and  non- 
members  and  utilizing  them  for  productive  agricultural  pur- 
poses in  their  immediate  neighborhoods  and  for  creating  great 
interlocked  financial  and  commercial  systems  for  helping  one 
another  in  all  parts  of  the  Empire,  may  be  formed  and  dis- 
solved almost  at  will  and  without  expense  under  the  German 
law.  This  law  is  not  an  intricate  code  but  is  embodied  in 
one  simple  statute  enacted  in  1889  which  applies  to  all  kinds 
of  cooperative  associations  aKke. 

By  this  law  seven  persons  may  form  a  cooperative  asso- 
ciation by  filing  articles  of  agreement  with  the  recorder  of  the 
district  court,  and  when  so  registered,  it  may  own  stock  in 
or  join  another  association  or  cooperative  corporation.    Tliis 


314  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

enables  a  weak  fagot  to  become  a  fasces  hard  to  break,  as  the 
Buropean  saying  is,  which  serves  as  a  supporting  beam  or 
stanchion  in  the  great  systems  which  have  been  created. 

Share  capital  is  required.  The  number  and  size  of  the 
shares,  however,  is  not  prescribed  but  each  member  must  hold 
at  least  one  and  pay  in  ten  per  cent  of  its  value  upon  sub- 
scription. Dividends  may  be  forbidden,  while  the  articles 
of  agreement  may  declare  that  even  the  assets  shall  not  be 
distributed  among  the  members  upon  dissolution.  This 
provision  was  inserted  to  favor  the  Eaiffeisen  societies,  which 
can  thus  live  up  to  their  principles  by  making  the  size  of 
shares  merely  nominal  and  writing  all  profits  to  the  reserves. 
Each  society  must  create  a  reserve,  and  must  state  in  its 
articles  what  portion  of  the  profits  shall  be  annually  set  aside 
for  it  and  the  minimum  at  which  it  shall  be  maintained. 
Members  have  no  interest  in  the  reserve,  which  is  in- 
divisible. 

A  society  may  expel  a  member  for  losing  his  civil  rights, 
for  joining  another  society,  or  for  changing  his  residence,  and 
the  articles  of  agreement  may  of  course  assign  other  reasons 
for  expidsion  and  lay  down  rules  for  admission.  If  retire- 
ment or  expulsion  occur,  the  motive  or  cause  must  be  entered 
on  the  register  at  the  district  court.  This  register  must 
always  be  kept  up  to  date  with  the  record  of  the  members 
who  are  admitted  as  well  as  of  those  who  are  retired.  Mem- 
bers may  retire  at  the  end  of  the  year  upon  giviag  previous 
notice  in  writing,  which  the  society  cannot  fix  at  less  than 
three  months  or  longer  than  two  years.  The  amount  of  the 
shares  must  be  returned  within  six  months  after  member- 
ship ceases.  Members  cannot  transfer  shares  except  upon 
consent  of  the  society  and  then  only  to  other  members.  No 
matter  how  many  shares  a  member  may  own  he  has  but  one 
vote  and  he  cannot  hold  more  than  one  proxy.  Proxies  are 
allowed  only  for  members  who  are  women,  corporations  and 
associations.  Thus  the  actual  presence  of  the  members  at 
the  annual  and  other  meetings  is  assured,  while  the  wealthy 
are  prevented  from  gaining  the  control. 

The  liability  assumed  by  members  may  be  one  of  three 


GEEMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PRESENT  315 

kinds.  Members  may  be  made  directly  liable  without  limit 
to  the  society  and  its  creditors ;  or  liable  •without  limit  to  the 
society  for  assessments  to  meet  its  debts  but  not  to  its  cred- 
itors; or  directly  liable  to  both  the  society  and  its  creditors 
but  only  for  a  fixed  sum,  'which,  however,  must  never  be 
lower  than  the  face  value  of  the  shares.  Among  these  three 
a  form  of  responsibility  may  be  found  to  suit  any  group  of 
cooperatives,  large  or  small.  An  unlimited  society  is  con- 
sidered in  failing  circumstances  if  its  assets,  including  cap- 
ital and  reserves,  do  not  suffice  to  meet  its  debts;  and  a  lim- 
ited society,  if  the  excess  of  debts  over  assets  is  greater  than 
one-fo\irth  of  the  aggregate  liability  assumed  by  members  on 
their  shares.  A  society  is  dissolved  by  a  three-fourths'  vote 
of  the  members  or  by  being  forced  into  bankruptcy.  The 
claims  of  creditors  are  barred  if  not  presented  within  two 
years.  A  member  who  pays  more  than  an  equitable  share 
has  the  rights  of  a  creditor  against  the  society  for  the  amount 
overpaid. 

The  same  kind  of  administration  is  provided  for  all  co- 
operative associations,  whether  they  be  banks,  trading  or  other 
concerns,  and  this  has  brought  about  complete  uniformity 
of  organization  and  business  methods.  It  consists  of  a  com- 
mittee of  management  of  two,  and  a  board  of  supervision 
of  three,  shareholders,  elected  at  the  annual  meeting,  unless 
the  articles  of  agreement  designate  some  other  number  and 
manner  of  appointment.  They  must  also  fix  the  term  of 
office.  No  member  may  serve  simultaneously  on  both  bodies. 
The  committee  transacts  the  actual  business;  the  board  must 
supervise  it  and  keep  itself  informed  regarding  the  affairs  of 
the  society.  Salaries  may  be  granted  but  the  board  cannot 
receive  compensation  based  on  a  percentage  of  the  profits 
or  returns  from  any  transaction.  This  practically  takes  away 
all  temptation  to  speculate  or  undertake  risky  ventures.  The 
shareholders  must  determine  at  their  annual  meeting  the 
total  amount  of  money  which  may  be  borrowed  or  received  on 
deposit  for  the  succeeding  year  and  the  maximum  of  credit 
to  be  accorded  to  members.  A  society  may  have  one  or  more 
objects,  all  of  them  being  indicated  in  its  title,  and  may  do 


316  ETJEAL    CREDITS 

business  with  outsiders,  but  a  credit  society  may  extend  credit 
to  members  only. 

The  alternative  which  the  law  allows  a  society  of  hav- 
ing its  obligatory  biennial  audit  made  by  a  union  instead  of 
by  an  expert  appointed  by  the  court  may  be  exercised  only 
when  it  belongs  to  a  union  which  has  no  financial  or  com- 
mercial objects  and  whose  sole  purpose,  besides  auditing,  is 
the  care  of  the  common  economic  interests  of  its  adherents. 
The  board  of  supervision  must  take  part  in  the  audit  and 
the  report  of  it  must  be  submitted  to  the  shareholders  at 
their  next  annual  meeting.  A  certificate  stating  that  the 
audit  has  been  taken  must  be  forwarded  to  the  union  and 
filed  with  the  recorder  of  the  district  court.  The  annual 
statements  showing  the  financial  condition  of  the  society 
and  the  number  of  members  retired,  admitted  and  remain- 
ing, together  with  aU  matters  of  importance  relating  to  its 
afiairs,  must  be  published  in  the  ofiBcial  newspapers ;  thus  com- 
plete publicity  is  assured.  No  special  privileges  are  granted 
except  exemption  from  certain  taxes  and  the  state  aid  men- 
tioned above. 

In  1913  there  were  26,576  rural  cooperative  societies  reg- 
istered under  this  law  in  Germany.  Of  these  98  were  cen- 
tral institutions;  16,927  credit  societies;  2,409  supply  socie- 
ties ;  3,313  dairies ;  175  milk-sellLng  stations ;  and  3,654  socie- 
ties for  various  other  purposes.  Thus  the  credit  societies 
comprise  two-thirds  of  the  whole.  They  began  to  appear 
in  numbers  in  the  nineties  of  the  last  century,  and  since  then 
they  have  been  increasing  by  leaps  and  bounds.  It  has  been 
no  unusual  thing  for  hundreds  of  new  societies  to  be  formed 
in  a  year.  They  are  unevenly  distributed  geographically. 
Many  parts  of  the  country  still  lack  them,  and  much  re- 
mains to  be  done  even  in  Germany  in  extending  cooperation. 

The  average  membership  of  each  rural  society  is  under 
100  and  its  area  of  operations  contains  less  than  2,000  souls. 
The  members  are  drawn  from  various  occupations;  among 
them  are  found  country  merchants,  artisans,  laborers,  farm 
hands,  tenants,  school  teachers,  priests,  preachers,  and  local 
public  ofi&cials.    But  about  70  per  cent  are  farmers,  and  the 


GEEMAN    SYSTEMS    AT    PRESENT  317 

majority  are  heads  of  families  and  many  own  their  own  land. 
Over  93  per  cent  of  the  societies  have  imposed  imlimited  lia- 
bility. A  great  many  credit  societies  of  the  Imperial  Fed- 
eration and  independent  unions,  like  the  Eaiffeisen  societies, 
supply  their  members  with  seed,  fodder,  and  fertilizer,  sell 
or  rent  implements  and  machines  to  them,  and  buy  and  sell 
their  products.  Wherever  there  is  no  regular  supply  asso- 
ciation, the  credit  society  invariably  takes  its  place  and  acts 
as  the  commercial  center  so  as  to  attract  members  from  the 
better  classes  by  their  conveniences  and  cheap  prices  for 
agricultural  necessities.  In  addition  to  material  objects  the 
societies  are  active  in  taking  care  of  the  general  welfare  of 
their  members,  and  some  of  them  have  founded  libraries, 
literary  clubs,  kindergartens,  schools  and  fire  brigades,  and 
attend  to  the  sick  and  the  burial  of  the  dead. 

The  salaries  of  ofBcers,  if  any  are  paid  at  all,  are  very 
small.  Half  a  dollar  or  a  dollar  as  attendance  fee  is  the 
usual  sum.  The  chairmanship  of  the  committee  of  manage- 
ment is  the  most  important  oflBce  and  effort  is  made  to  get 
the  most  prominent  man  in  the  village  to  take  this  honorary 
position.  The  secretary  is  sometimes  the  village  school 
teacher,  a  local  public  official  or  a  clerk  familiar  with  keeping 
accounts.  The  customary  salary  for  this  officer  is  $75  to  $200 
a  year  in  a  society  with  80  to  120  members.  The  office  of 
the  local  society  is  generally  at  his  home,  and  the  popular 
time  for  transacting  business  is  Sunday  after  church  or  in 
the  evenings  of  holidays.  A  strong  box,  a  desk,  a  few  chairs 
and  stationery,  amounting  in  value  to  a  couple  hundred  of 
dollars,  are  all  the  office  fitstures  and  supplies  needed  for  a 
rural  cooperative  society. 

The  credit  extended  by  a  local  society  is  expected  to  be- 
used  for  some  productive  or  provident  purpose  and  this  pur- 
pose is  entered  on  the  minutes  by  the  committee  when  the 
application  is  granted.  But  the  larger  societies  do  not  watch 
the  use  closely  after  once  being  satisfied  with  ithe  security 
given  by  the  borrower.  The  local  societies  do  not  make  a 
practice  of  according  real-estate  credit.  Nevertheless  they 
have  over  $70,000,000  of  mortgages  on  hand,  which  were 


318  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

mostly  taken  on  loans  granted  to  members  to  buy  off  prior 
encumbrances  bearing  higb  interest  rates  or  for  buying  out 
coheirs,  as  security  for  the  purchase  price  of  farms  sold  to 
members  by  the  society  itself,  or  to  protect  its  claims  and 
the  property  of  the  borrowing  members  from  outside  cred- 
itors. The  mortgages  rim  five  or  ten  years,  and  are  repaya- 
ble ia  yearly  instalments. 

The  bulk  of  the  loan  business  of  the  local  credit  societies 
is  usually  done  on  promissory  notes  or  by  extending  credit 
on  current  accounts.  Security  is  always  required,  the-  pre- 
vailing form  being  the  indorsement  of  two  or  more  sureties. 
These  loans  as  a  rule  run  from  one  year  up  to  six  years 
and  are  repayable  in  annual  or  semi-annual  instalments.  On 
current  accounts  the  debtor  has  to  pay  back  a  certain  per- 
centage of  the  overdraft  within  similar  intervals.  All  socie- 
ties retain  the  right  of  recalling  credit  upon  four  weeks' 
notice. 

The  funds  for  carrying  on  business  come  from  the  en- 
trance fees,  capital,  reserves,  deposits,  and  money  borrowed 
from  the  regional  or  union  banks  or  outside  lenders  upon 
the  collective  liability  of  the  members.  The  entrance  fees 
are  rarely  over  a  dollar.  In  associations  having  share  cap- 
ital the  individual  shares  range  from  a  quarter  of  a  dollar 
up  to  $1,000  in  the  large  and  old-established  societies,  but 
the  actual  paid-up  amount  in  the  Imperial  Federation  is  only 
about  $5  per  share,  since  the  societies  are  content  to  let  mem- 
bers keep  the  cash  because  they  can  draw  on  their  liability 
at  any  time  to  raise  necessary  funds  in  case  of  losses  or 
unexpected  needs.  The  deposits  comprise  the  greatest  por- 
tion of  the  working  funds,  and  the  societies  pay  as  high  in- 
•terest  on  deposits  as  possible  in  order  to  attract  them  from 
the  savings  banks  and  other  moneyed  institutions  in 
the  neighborhood.  Good  rates  can  be  easily  given  because 
the  profits  of  the  local  credit  societies  are  not  consumed 
in  paying  large  dividends  or  salaries,  while  they  have  the 
safest  kind  of  investment  for  funds  and  can  put  them  to  as 
profitable  uses  as  can  any  other  lenders.  Their  dividends 
never  exceed  three  or  at  the  most  four  per  cent,  and  the  cost 


GEEMAK    SYSTEMS    AT    PEESENT  319 

of  their  maaiagement  rarely  goes  over  $100  or  $150  a  year 
each. 

The  statistics  of  1911,  coveriag  95  per  cent  of  all  rural 
cooperative  credit  associations  registered  under  the  law,  show 
the  strong  position  and  the  enormous  amount  of  business  done 
by  these  little  local  units.  Accordirig  to  these  figures  the 
aggregate  of  the  funds  owned  by  the  credit  associations  was 
$23,358,374,  or  $1,545  per  society  and  $15.12  per  member. 
Of  this  aggregate  $7,652,204  was  paid-up  capital  on  shares, 
or  $518  per  society  and  $5.04  per  member;  and  $15,710,769 
reserves,  or  $1,060  per  society  and  $11.04  per  member. 

The  total  amount  of  funds  not  their  own  in  the  posses- 
sion of  these  societies  (for  14,729  societies  only)  was  $543,- 
_701,409.  Of  this  amount  $443,899,656  was  deposits,  $52,154,- 
124  was  in  current  accounts,  and  the  rest  probably  borrowed 
money.  The  deposits  averaged  $30,134  per  society  and 
$307.44  per  member. 

The  total  assets  were  $572,968,588  or  $38,740  per  society, 
for  the  same  number  of  societies.  The  total  liabilities  were 
$569,558,596,  or  $38,668  per  society. 

The  loans  and  overdrafts  outstanding  at  the  end  of  the 
year  amounted  to  $446,565,926  (for  14,729  societies  only), 
or  $30,316  per  society  and  $308  per  member. 

The  loans  and  advances  on  current  accounts  made  to  mem- 
bers during  the  year  reached  $247,837,766  (for  13,565  socie- 
ties only),  or  $18,264  per  society  and  $188  per  member.  Ee- 
payments  made  by  borrowing  members  were  $215,790,436,  or 
$15,907  per  society,  and  $163  per  member. 

The  deposits  made  during  the  year  were  $137,996,121,  or 
$6,512  per  society  and  $102  per  depositor  for  the  same  num- 
ber of  banks. 

Five  per  cent  of  the  rural  credit  societies  are  omitted 
from  these  statistics,  neither  do  they  include  any  of  the  peo- 
ple's banks  allied  to  the  national  or  Schulze-Delitzsch  Fed- 
eration. Over  29  per  cent  of  the  members  of  the  952  banks, 
in  this  Federation  ia  1911  were  farmers  or  persons  engaged 
in  agricultural  pursuits ;  and  their  savings,  earnings  and  busi- 
ness represent  perhaps  a  corresponding  portion  of  the  $397,- 


'320  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

418,550  of  worHng  funds  and  $1,107,209,999  of  transactions 
during  that  year.  All  these  would  have  to  be  added  to  show 
the  true  and  complete  state  of  affairs.  The  annual  turnover 
of  the  banks  of  the  Sehnlze-Delitzseh  Federation  is  very  much 
greater  than  that  of  the  banks  in  the  Imperial  and  Greneral 
Federations.  This  is  owing  to  the  fact  that  most  of  the 
business  of  the  city  banks  is  done  on  three-months'  paper, 
while  that  of  the  rural  credit  societies  is  done  on  relatively 
long-time  loans  or  advances. 


CHAPTEE   XXIV 
'AGEiCULTUEAIi    CREDIT    IN    FRANCE 

Early  Cooperative  Movement  in  France. — Credit  Agricole  Mutuel. — 
History  of  Society. — SociSt6  du  Credit  Agricole. — Its  Failure 
Due  to  Method  of  Organization. — Further  Attempts.— Laws  of 
1867  and  1884. — ^Associations  and  Cornices. — Syndicats  Profes- 
sionels. — Syndieal  Banks  and  Connection  with  Bank  of  France. — 
Organization  and  Operation  of  Banks  of  the  System. — Govern- 
ment Loans. 

CooPEEATrvD  credit  for  farmers  was  agitated  in  France 
before  it  was  put  in  practice  in  any  other  country.  All  the 
earliest  French  Utopians  and  conxmunists,  realizing  that  agri- 
culture was  the  greatest  source  of  wealth,  suggested  ways  and 
means  of  supplying  it  with  funds  or  credit  based  on  asso- 
ciated action.  Fourier  devised  for  his  phalanxes  rural  count- 
ing houses  for  advancing  money  to  farmers  on  their  crops. 
Vidal  and  Pecqueur  proposed  that  the  loan  of  30  million 
dollars  which  they  wished  the  state  to  make  to  agriculture 
should  be  allotted  among  associations  of  farmers.  Louis 
Blanc  wanted  the  farmers  in  his  colonies  to  be  iinanced  by 
warehouses  in  which  they  were  to  be  required  to  store  their 
produce,  while  Proudhon  proposed  to  have  the  notes  which 
his  Bank  of  Exchange  was  to  issue  on  the  security  of  stored 
produce  to  be  guaranteed  by  all  its  adherents.  These  vagarious 
schemes  were  not  cooperative,  properly  speaking,  but  they 
were  inspired  by,  if  they  did  not  create,  the  spirit  of  mutu- 
ality which  subsequently  became  a  dominant  feature  of  the 
industrial  and  agricultural  life  of  France. 

This  spirit  began  to  manifest  itself  in  the  early  part 
of  the  last  century,  and  the  financing  of  the  working  classes 
who  attempted  to  combine  for  their  mutual  protection  and 

321 


323  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

assistance  was  the  first  project  considered.  The  Provident 
Aid  Bank  was  founded  at  Limoges  in  1830,  the  Fraternal 
Bank  for  Small  Commerce  at  Cognac  in  1848,  the  Bonnard 
Exchange  Bank  of  Marseilles  in  1849,  and  the  Mutual  Com- 
mercial Exchange  Bank  by  grape  growers  at  Montreuil  and 
Vincennes  in  1857.  The  latter  institution  is  called  the  mother 
of  cooperative  credit  in  France  and  it  served  as  a  model  for 
many  others  within  a  few  years  after  its  foundation.  Beluze 
started  mutual  banks  for  laborers  in  Paris  in  1863.  In  1866 
there  were  over  60  of  these  banks  at  Paris  and  in  the  depart- 
ments, when  Napoleon  III  founded  the  Bank  for  Coopera- 
tive Associations  with  a  capital  of  $100,000.  Leon  Say 
(Minister  of  Finance,  1872-1882)  also  founded  a  bank  for 
cooperatives  at  Paris,  while  others  were  started  at  Lyon,  Lille, 
Mulhouse,  Strasbourg,  Colmar,  Saint-Etienne  and  Marseilles. 
These  banks  were  in  the  cities  and  nearly  all  of  them  had 
disappeared  by  1869.  Ludovic  de  Besse,  a  Capuchin  monk, 
took  up  the  work  again  in  1878  and  by  1886  he  had  formed 
18  banks  which  he  designed  primarily  for  Catholics,  but  he 
gloried  in  having  some  Jews  among  them.  In  1885  Louis 
Milcent,  with  the  assistance  of  Paul  Bouvet,  a  wealthy  timber 
merchant,  founded  at  Poligny,  in  the  assembly  district  of 
Jura,  a  cooperative  bank  composed  entirely  of  farmers.  By 
1887  an  active  movement  for  cooperative  credit  was  launched 
under  the  leadership  of  Father  Ludovic  and  Eugene  Eostand, 
father  of  the  dramatic  poet,  joined  later  by  Charles  Eayneri, 
who  sent  invitations  to  20  known  societies  for  a  convention 
held  in  1889.  About  this  time  also  Jules  Meline,  who  has 
been  President  of  the  Chamber  of  Deputies,  Minister  of 
Agriculture,  Chairman  of  the  National  Council  and  Prime 
Minister,  began  to  interest  himself  in  the  propagation  of  co- 
operative credit.  In  1890  Louis  Durand,  a  lawyer  at  Lyon, 
was  delegated  by  the  Northeastern  Union  of  Agricultural 
Associations  to  make  an  investigation  of  farm  finance;  his 
remarkable  book,  Credit  agricole  en  France  et  a  I'Etranger, 
was  published  in  1891.  In  1893  Durand  founded  two  credit 
societies.  The  first  of  these,  started  in  March  at  Lange  with 
the  help  of  the  Abbot  Eagu,  was  the  first  society  of  the 


AGEICULTTJEAL    CEEDIT    IN   FRANCE      3^3 

Eaiffeisen  type  to  appear  in  France.  The  other,  composed 
of  workmen,  was  started  in  April  at  Bagneres  de  Bigorre 
with  the  help  of  Mr.  Soule  and.Dussert.  Durand  immedi- 
ately organized  these  two  credit  societies  into  the  Federation 
of  Farmers'  and  Workmen's  Banks  with  Unlimited  Liability. 
In  July  of  the  same  year  Charles  Eayneri  formed  a  society  of 
the  EaifEeisen  type  at  Castellar  through  the  Central  Federa- 
tion of  People's  Credit  which  he  had  organized  a  few  months 
before.  In  1894  a  law  for  rural  cooperative  banks  was 
placed  on  the  statute  book,  and  by  subsequent  legislation  most 
of  the  banks  which  have  been  formed  under  this  law  have 
been  induced  to  join  the  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  which  is  a 
decentralized  system  of  local  and  regional  cooperative  banks, 
at  present  fostered  by  the  state,  for  granting  short-  and  long- 
term  credit  both  to  individual  farmers  and  to  agricultural 
cooperative  associations. 

The  Central  Federation  of  People's  Credit  and  the  Fed- 
eration of  Farmers'  and  Workmen's  Banks  with  Unliroited 
Liability  stiU  exist.  The  former  is  neutral  as  regards  politics 
and  religion.  The  local  banks  affiliated  with  it  comprise  those 
connected  with  the  People's  Bank  of  Menton,  managed  by  Mr. 
Eayneri,  and  those  which  were  formed  after  the  ideas  of  Mr. 
Eostand.  They  depend  principally  on  the  savings  banks  of 
their  neighborhoods  for  obtaining  money  to  lend  to  members 
but  sometimes  resort  to  the  state  for  aid.  The  Federation  of 
Farmers'  and  Workmen's  Banks  is  almost  exclusively  Cath- 
olic. A  few  of  its  local  banks  are  connected  with  regional 
banks  which  receive  aid  from  the  state  but  the  majority 
depend  on  their  own  resources  or  on  regional  banks  which 
they  themselves  have  created.  The  total  number  of  banks 
belonging  to  these  two  federations  is  estimated  at  between 
800  and  1,100,  but  their  members  are  largely  workmen  in 
the  cities. 

The  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  on  the  other  hand,  is  entirely 
agricultural,  and  it  embraces  all  the  agricultural  cooperative 
banks  in  France  outside  of  these  two  federations  except  131, 
128  of  which  have  8,612  members.  In  1912  the  Credit  Agri- 
cole Mutuel  comprised  98  state-aided  regional  banks  and 


334  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

4,204  local  banks  or  credit  societies  with  215,695  farmer 
members.  A  Bureau  of  Supervision  and  Control  has  been 
established  in  the  Miaistry  of  Agriculture  for  the  banks  which 
receive  aid  from  the  state,  all  of  which  are  aflBliated  to  the 
Central  Federation  of  Agricultural  Syndicates  of  rrance. 
This  body,  established  for  propaganda  and  organization  work, 
keeps  all  the  regional  banks  in  communication  with  each 
other.  It  publishes  a  semi-monthly  bulletin  with  statistics 
of  the  funds  that  are  idle  or  needed  in  each  bank,  interest 
rates  and  other  useful  information,  and  encourages  mutuality 
and  interdependence  in  the  system. 

The  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  founded  about  15  years  ago, 
now  covers  the  entire  country.  There  is  at  least  one  regional 
bank  in  each  of  the  86  states  and  the  territory  of  Belfort  into 
which  Prance  is  divided.  Attached  to  each  regional  bank 
are  on  an  average  42  local  banks  or  credit  societies  with  about 
50  members  each,  whose  territory  as  a  rule  is  confined  to  a 
parish  or  a  commune.  This  vast  system,  which  it  is  hoped 
through  its  decentralization  eventually  will  bring  credit  facil- 
ities to  the  very  doors  of  all  the  French  farmers,  sprang 
from  the  movement  set  on  foot  by  the  inquiries  propounded 
in  1826  by  the  rich  banker  Casimir  Perier,  who  subsequently 
became  Minister  of  the  Interior.  The  first  result  of  this 
movement  was  the  enactment  of  the  law  and  the  establish- 
ment in  1852  of  the  Credit  Foneier  for  land  credit,  as  re- 
lated in  an  earlier  chapter.  But  it  was  soon  realized  that 
the  organization  of  land  credit  was  bringing  no  relief  to 
small  farmers  and  that  something  else  had  to  be  done  in 
order  to  rescue  them  from  the  usurious  bondage  iato  which 
they  had  fallen.  The  reports  made  by  Charles  Edward  Eoyer 
in  1844  and  Jean-Baptiste  Josseau  in  1851,  at  the  instance 
of  the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  showed  that  the  various  coun- 
tries they  had  visited  contained  banks  for  granting  short- 
term  credit  as  well  as  banks  for  long-term  credit  for  agri- 
cultural purposes,  and  the  Government  again  undertook  the 
study  of  the  unsolved  problem.  In  1854  Napoleon  III  dele- 
gated Leonce  de  Lavergne  to  investigate  the  credit  institu- 
tions of  Great  Britain  and  the  work  of  Schulze-Delitzsch  and 


AGEICULTUEAL    CEBDIT    IK    FRANCE      325 

Eaiffeisen,  whose  fame  though  still  new  was  beginning  to 
spread  over  the  borders  of  Germany.  Consular  agents  also 
were  instructed  to  make  researches  in  other  parts  of  Europe. 

In  1860  a  large  commission  with  M.  Josseau  as  secretary 
was  oflBeially  assembled  to  examine  the  material  which  had 
been  gathered  and  to  make  recommendations.  It  ignored 
cooperation  and  advised  the  creation  of  a  large  central  insti- 
tution with  the  aid  of  the  state.  A  law  was  accordingly 
enacted  in  that  year  by  virtue  of  which  the  Societe  du  Credit 
Agxicole  was  organized  in  1861.  The  Credit  Foncier  was 
compelled  to  supply  the  $4,000,000  of  capital,  and  its  presi- 
dent and  vice-presidents  to  act  as  the  officers  of  this  ill- 
starred  concern,  long  since  dissolved.  The  Government 
pledged  itself  to  advance  a  maximum  of  $80,000  annually  in 
case  profits  should  not  suffice  to  pay  expenses  and  a  dividend 
of  four  per  cent  a  year.  The  objects  of  the  Societe  du  Credit 
Agricole  were  to  extend  credit  to  agriculture  and  allied  indus- 
tries, but  no  restrictions  were  imposed  against  dealing  with 
any  class  of  persons,  and  it  was  empowered  to  discount  pa- 
per, to  make  loans  on  real  or  personal  security,  and  to  issue 
five-year  debentures  of  $25  or  more  against  its  loans. 

In  1870  this  great  agricultural  bank  had  500  correspond- 
ents whose  business  with  it  amounted  to  $83,619,000;  17 
branches  with  $143,121,800  of  discounts;  and  two  subsidiary 
companies,  one  of  which  had  a  capital  of  $1,200,000,  and 
the  other  assets  of  over  $6,000,000.  The  capital  of  the  cen- 
tral concern  was  then  $8,000,000,  its  deposits  $1,053,400, 
accounts  current  $698,000,  secured  loans  $13,579,200,  and 
discounts  $247,778,800,  while  its  debentures  in  circulation  ex- 
ceeded $18,000,000.  But  this  splendid  showing  meant  very 
little  to  agriculture.  The  farmers  could  not  be  induced  to 
deal  with  it,  and  owing  to  the  lack  of  their  business,  the 
bank  began  to  engage  in  speculative  enterprises.  Among 
these  was  the  Egyptian  affair.  By  1876  it  had  lent  to  the 
Government  of  the  Khedive  $33,649,265.  This  money  was 
obtained  from  the  Credit  Foncier,  which  in  making  the  ad- 
vance impaired  its  capital  and  exhausted  its  disposable  funds 
raised  by  the  sale  of  debentures.     The  security  was  Suez 


336  RUEAL   CEEDITS 

Canal  stock  and  Egyptian  obligations  of  various  kinds.  In 
1876  the  Khedive  suspended  payment  and  the  Soeiete  du 
Credit  Agricole  immediately  went  to  pieces.  The  Credit 
Fonder  was  badly  involved  in  the  ruin,  but  by  carefully 
nursing  the  assets  which  were  left,  it  finally  wound  up  the 
affairs  of  the  bank  in  1881  at  a  net  loss  of  $1,400,000.  From 
the  point  of  view  of  agriculture,  the  Sqciete  du  Credit  Agri- 
cole  was  doomed  from  the  start  because  it  was  an  attempt 
to  organize  credit  by  beginning  at  the  top.  Such  efforts  gen- 
erally have  ended  in  disaster  or  brought  unsatisfactory  results. 
As  soon  as  the  plan  of  a  central  institution  began  to  prove 
a  failure,  the  Government  in  1863  resumed  the  study  of 
short-term  agricultural  credit  with  renewed  energy,  and  in 
1866  appointed  a  second  commission  to  reexamine  the  many 
projects  before  it,  which  kept  it  at  work  until  the  Franco- 
Prussian  war  in  1870.  The  question  was  taken  up  again 
after  the  restoration  of  peace  and  became  one  of  the  most 
important  public  issues,  because  the  farmers  by  that  time 
had  become  so  burdened  with  debt  or  stagnated  from  the  lack 
of  capital  that  agriculture  was  retrograding  to  the  danger  of 
the  country's  welfare.  In  1878  an  International  Congress  on 
Agriculture  was  held  in  the  Trocadero  in  Paris  under  the 
auspices  of  some  of  the  most  notable  persons  in  France  and 
other  countries.  In  1879  a  third  commission  was  appointed 
and  another  inquiry  abroad  made  through  consular  agents, 
while  experts  investigated  conditions  at  home.  This  inquiry 
resulted  in  1881  in  recommendations  for  the  amendment  of 
the  laws  relating  to  pledges,  chattel  mortgages,  commercial 
paper  and  bankruptcy,  with  the  object  of  eliminating  the 
technicalities  which  prevented  the  banks  and  money  lenders 
from  taking  the  security  or  discounting  the  notes  and  biUs 
of  farmers.  Debates  in  the  Assembly  on  these  subjects  con- 
tinued until  1898,  when  a  law  was  enacted  which,  with 
amendments  in  1906,  enabled  a  farmer  to  give  as  security 
for  a  loan  a  mortgage  on  his  live  stock,  chattels  and  personal 
belongings,  whether  they  were  left  in  his  own  buildings  or 
on  his  own  land  or  in  the  possession  of  a  trustee  or  of  any 
association  of  which  he  might  be  a  member.    This  right,  up 


AGEICULTUEAL   CEEDIT   IN   FEANCB      327 

to  that  time  denied  to  fanners,  placed  tkem  on  a  footing  of 
equality  with  merchants  and  industrial  persons  as  borrow- 
ers in  financial  circles  and  brought  about  what  the  French 
call  the  "commercialization  of  agriculture." 

The  law  of  1860,  mentioned  above,  was  the  first  attempt 
made  in  Prance  to  solve  the  problem  of  short-term  credit 
for  farmers.  Its  basic  idea  was  the  creation  of  a  large  cen- 
tral bank  under  the  auspices  of  the  state  with  the  aid  of 
public  funds.  The  Credit  Fonder,  to  which  the  Societe  du 
Credit  Agricole  was  annexed,  is,  it  will  be  remembered,  a 
semi-governmental  institution.  The  farmers  were  not  called 
upon  to  contribute  anything  towards  the  support  of  this  bank, 
nor  were  they  given  any  part  in  its  organization  or  manage- 
ment. They  were  expected  only  to  be  the  customers  for  the 
easy  credit  that  it  was  intended  to  accord.  The  disastrous 
but  natural  failure  of  the  first  state  agricultural  bank,  how- 
ever, did  not  swerve  the  Government  from  its  policy,  mani- 
fested as  far  back  as  1848,  and  now  successfully  accomplished, 
as  will  be  seen  later,  of  extending  public  aid  to  farmers,  but 
it  put  an  end  to  all  plans  for  the  formation  of  a  centralized 
system  of  agricultural  credit  to  which  the  farmers  were  to 
be  connected  simply  as  beneficiaries. 

The  miserable  collapse  of  the  Societe  du  Credit  Agricole 
was  the  best  lesson  France  and  Europe  ever  received  in  agri- 
cultural credit,  and  while  it  was  slow  to  be  appreciated,  the 
effect  of  the  lesson  has  been  all  the  more  permanent  and  use- 
ful. Since  then  decentralization  has  been  recognized  as  the 
true  principle,  and  the  systems  since  formed  for  independent 
farmers  capable  of  taking  care  of  themselves  have  been  con- 
structed on  the  idea  of  building  up  from  the  ground,  arid  cre- 
ating credit  facilities  at  the  very  doors  of  the  farm  homes. 
This  idea  of  decentralization  had  strong  advocates  from  the 
beginning  in  France,  but  its  reduction  to  practice  was  finally 
hastened  by  two  other  laws  which  were  enacted  without  any 
bearing  on  farm  credits  and  even  without  any  thought  that 
they  would  influence  the  solution  of  that  problem.  Yet  by 
opening  the  way  for  private  initiative  and  associated  action, 
they  led  to  the  introduction  of  cooperation  for  all  agricul- 


328  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

tural  purposes,  credit  included,  and  gave  to  it  the  special 
feature  of  syndicalism  along  the  lines  of  which  cooperative 
credit  subsequently  developed  in  France 

A  brief  reference  to  history  is  necessary  in  order  to  ex- 
plain the  purpose  of  placing  on  the  statute  books  these 
two  laws,  one  of  which  was  enacted  in  1867  and  the  other  in 
1884.  In  1791  the  revolutionists,  being  socialistic  in  tendency 
and  also  in  constant  dread  of  political  conspiracies,  considered 
all  associations  and  corporations  to  be  inimical  to  the  con- 
stitution and  declared  that  none  should  exist  or  be  formed 
except  by  special  act.  "'No  citizen  of  the  same  civic  state 
or  profession,"  they  enacted,  "nor  builders,  tradespeople,  la- 
borers or  persons  of  any  mystery  or  art  whatsoever,  shall 
when  assembled  elect  presidents,  secretaries  or  treasurers,  keep 
records,  pass  resolutions,  or  adopt  by-laws  in  reference  to  their 
pretended  common  interests."  The  penal  code  compiled 
under  Napoleon  Bonaparte  in  1810  retained  the  substance  of 
this  law  of  the  First  Eepublic,  but  so  amended  it  as  to  read : 
"No  association  of  more  than  20  persons  aiming  to  meet 
every  day  or  at  stated  intervals  for  religious,  literary,  po- 
litical or  other  objects,  shall  be  formed  except  with  consent 
of  the  Government  and  upon  conditions  imposed  by  public 
authority."  The  law  of  1834,  enacted  on  the  return  of  the 
Bourbons,  retained  this  provision  and  added  that  the  con- 
sent of  the  Government  was  always  revocable. 

This  restriction  prevented  all  freedom  of  action.  The 
only  way  in  which  a  company  or  association  could  be  formed 
was  to  procure  a  license  under  a  special  act  or  decree.  This 
was  usually  a  lengthy  and  expensive  procedure,  while  the 
license  was  uncertain  in  its  duration  even  after  it  had  been 
obtained.  Such  conditions  blocked  industrial  progress  and 
also  made  it  impossible  to  form  with  ease  the  little  societies 
so  necessary  for  the  full  play  of  cooperation.  Consequently 
urgent  demands  for  modernization  came  from  all  sides  and 
could  not  be  denied.  The  law  of  1867  abrogated  the  restric- 
tion so  far  as  it  related  to  companies  and  substituted  a  general 
law  whereby  they  are  allowed  to  be  formed  by  any  number 
of  persons  simply  by  the  filing  of  articles  of  agreement  and 


AGEICTJLTUEAL   CEEDIT   IN   FEANCB      329 

complying  with  specified  regiilations.  This  law  further  pro- 
Tided  that  the  capital  stock  of  such  companies  may  be  made 
"susceptible  of  increase  by  successive  payments  of  sharehold- 
ers or  by  the  admission  of  new  shareholders,  or  of  diminish- 
ment  by  the  withdrawal  in  whole  or  in  part  of  their  shares." 
This  provision  was  inserted  on  the  request  of  followers  of 
Schulze-Delitzseh,  and  it  was  the  first  time  that  cooperation 
was  given  a  legal  status  in  Prance.  But  the  only  kind  of  a 
cooperative  society  allowed  thereunder  was  one  with  shares 
of  a  minimum  value  of  50  francs  ($10).  Thus  the  statutory 
recognition  was  not  complete,  since  the  EaifEeisen  type  of 
society  was  excluded,  but  it  was  enough  for  the  starting  of 
propaganda,  and  earnest  men  who  were  familiar  vnth  what 
was  being  done  in  Germany  and  across  the  Alps  in  upper 
Italy  by  Luigi  Luzzatti  began  gradually  to  prepare  the 
French  farmers  for  the  reception  of  cooperation.  In  1893 
the  minimum  for  shares  was  altogether  abolished  and  thus 
the  way  was  opened  for  Eaiffeisenism. 

The  second  piece  of  legislation,  the  law  of  1884,  applies 
to  associations.  It  provides  that  20  or  more  persons  of  the 
same  trade  or  calling,  or  trades  and  callings  connected  there- 
with, may  freely  form  an  association  without  being  required 
to  obtain  a  special  act  or  license  but  simply  by  filing  their 
articles  of  agreement  with  names  of  the  first  members  and 
officers  with  the  mayor  of  the  place  where  it  is  to  be  located 
and  with  the  prefect  of  the  Seine  at  Paris.  The  objects  of 
an  association  imder  this  law  are  confitned  to  the  study,  pro- 
tection and  promotion  of  the  common  economic  interests  of 
members,  be  they  industrial,  commercial  or  agricultural. 
Such  an  association  is  empowered  also  freely  to  combine  with 
other  associations  of  the  same  kind  and  purposes.  The  law 
■was  intended  primarily  for  trade,  commerce  and  the  working 
classes,  whose  representatives  were  chiefly  instrumental  in 
securing  its  passage.  The  word  "agricultural"  was  inserted 
as  an  afterthought  just  before  the  last  reading  to  round  out 
the  sentence,  according  to  tradition. 

But  contrary  to  all  expectations  this  law  became  useful 
mainly  for  agriculture   and  effected  the  salvation  of  the 


330  EUEAL    CREDITS 

small  farmers.  It  happened  to  be  enacted  at  the  height  of 
the  agricultural  crisis  which  had  been  precipitated  over  all 
Europe  by  the  long  continued  neglect  of  agriculture  and  the 
competition  of  American  with  domestic  grown  products  pro- 
moted by  cheap  oversea  transportation.  The  only  hope  of 
the  Prench  farmers  lay  in  combining  their  forces,  so  that 
they  could  buy  their  supplies  at  wholesale  prices,  improve 
their  methods  of  cultivation  by  the  interchange  of  useful 
information,  and  secure  by  their  united  vote  tariff  laws  and 
other  legislation  favorable  to  their  interests ;  and  they  imme- 
diately set  about  organizing  themselves  for  mutual  self-help. 
Within  a  year  39  associations  were  formed  under  this  law 
and  the  number  grew  thereafter  as  if  by  magic.  Ten  years 
after  its  enactment  there  were  1,888  associations  with  403,261 
members,  and  in  1911  there  were  5,058  associations  with 
778,189  members,  and  555  unions  with  2,392  adhering  asso- 
ciations. 

The  associations  which  came  into  existence  by  virtue  of 
the  law  of  1884  must  not  be  confused  vrith  the  many  agri- 
cultural societies,  one  of  which,  created  by  the  state  of 
Bretagne  for  the  district  of  lUe-et-Vilaine,  dates  back  to  1756 ; 
nor  with  the  cornices,  or  agricultural  committees,  which, 
appearing  first  around  1830  and  subsequently  regulated  by 
the  law  of  1851,  now  number  over  1,200.  The  agricultural 
societies  and  cornices  are  agronomic  groups  of  men  united 
for  holding  fairs,  awarding  prizes  and  advancing  the  agri- 
cultural interest  of  their  localities.  Nor  must  the  farmers' 
associations  be  confused  vrith  the  syndical  associations  which 
may  be  voluntarily  formed,  or  compelled  by  the  state  to  be 
formed,  by  landowners  to  undertake  works  of  common  utility, 
such  as  the  reclamation  of  land  by  drainage,  irrigation,  etc. 

The  associations  formed  imder  the  law  of  1884  are 
called  in  French  syndicats  professionels,  the  last  word  signi- 
fying a  trade  as  well  as  a  profession,  vocation  or  calling. 
The  difference  between  an  association  and  a  syndicat  in 
France  is  that  the  former  has  merely  a  conventional  form, 
while  the  latter  has  a  statutory  form  and  is  an  association 
organized  under  some  law  containing  the  regulations  respect- 


AGEICULTUEAL    CEEDIT    IN    FRANCE      331 

ing  its  powers  and  privileges.  French  agrieultural  syndicats 
are  counterparts  of  some  of  the  unions  of  the  agricultural 
cooperative  systems  of  Germany.  A  trade  union  is  called  a 
syndicat  in  France. 

The  law  of  1884  was  not  drafted  especially  for  coopera- 
tion. It  was  designed  for  all  kinds  of  associations  having 
no  object  of  gain,  and  its  evident  intent  is  that  they  should 
not  have  any  financial  or  business  affairs.  But  it  contained 
loopholes.  The  clauses  allowing  such  associations  to  promote 
the  economic  interests  of  members  and  also  to  make  invest- 
ments of  fees  and  contributions  received  from  them  were 
taken  advantage  of  to  favor  agricultural  cooperation,  and 
consequently  there  are  now  agricultural  syndicats  which  act 
as  agents  for  making  collective  purchases  and  sales  for  mem- 
bers, which  buy  for  and  sell  to  members  collectively  or  indi- 
vidually the  supplies  they  need,  which  own  warehouses  for 
the  storage  and  marketing  of  members'  products,  which  carry 
on  a  retail  trade  with  the  public  in  products  bought  from 
members,  which  publish  periodicals,  and  which  do-  various 
other  things  of  a  commercial  and  industrial  nature,  distrib- 
uting the  profits,  if  any,  as  rebates  to  members  or  keeping 
or  using  them  for  their  common  good.  These  broad  con- 
structions of  the  law  have  given  rise  to  much  litigation.  The 
court  at  Nancy  denied  to  agricultural  syndicats  the  rights 
of  cooperative  societies,  but  a  new  law  enacted  in  1901  cleared 
off  certain  legal  difficidties,  and  under  this  law  about  100 
syndicats  have  been  formed. 

The  circular  of  M.  Waldeck-Eosseau,  Minister  of  the 
Interior,  setting  forth  the  views  of  the  administration  on 
the  1884  law  at  the  time  of  its  passage  said: 

The  legislature,  imbued  with  the  idea  that  the  association  of 
individuals  according  to  their  professional  or  vocational  affinities 
is  less  an  arm  of  combat  than  an  instrument  of  moral,  intellec- 
tual and  material  progress,  has  given  to  the  syndicats  a  civil 
and  legal  personality  in  order  to  permit  them  to  use  their  power 
to  the  highest  degree  for  doing  good.  Owing  to  this  complete 
freedom  of  action  on  the  one  hand,  and  legal  civil  personality 
on  the  other  hand,  the  syndicats  are  able  to  unite  the  necessary 


332  RUEAL    CREDITS 

resources  for  creating  and  multiplying  among  other  persons 
useful  institutions  for  help  in  ease  of  need,  libraries,  lecture 
courses  and  bureaus  of  information  for  statistics,  investments 
and.  salaries,  and  mutual  credit  banks  and  cooperative  societies. 

The  first  syndicat  worked  along  the  lines  laid  down  in  this 
circular.  Scarcely  a  month  after  the  law  of  1884  went  into 
effect,  an  agricultural  syndicat  was  formed  for  Poligny,  and 
in  the  following  year  it  founded  for  the  farmers  affiliated 
with  it,  through  M.  Milcent,  the  bank  mentioned  above,  with 
shares  and  a  variable  capital  under  the  law  of  1867.  Tliis 
is  known  as  the  first  rural  cooperative  bank  in  France,  al- 
though a  syndicat  founded  by  Professor  Tanviraz  at  Blois 
in  1883  attempted  credit  in  an  elementary  way.  Another  was 
formed  shortly  afterwards  at  Senlis,  and  the  syndicate  thence- 
forth became  active  in  giving  a  cooperative  direction  to  agri- 
cultural credit. 

Thus  agricultural  cooperative  credit  made  its  appearance 
in  France  through  the  syndicats,  and  in  order  to  encourage 
its  progress  M.  Meline  proposed  that  the  1884  law  be  so 
amended  as  to  enable  syndicats  to  be  organized  for  extending 
credit  directly.  This  was  opposed  by  persons  who  wished 
another  central  agricultural  bank  to  be  organized  and  guar- 
anteed by  the  state.  France  has  ever  clung  to  its  idea  of 
helping  the  farmer  financially.  It  was  also  opposed  by  those 
who  still  wished  the  syndicats  to  remain  merely  the  agents 
or  instruments  for  creating,  directing  and  advising  coopera- 
tive societies  without  necessarily  being  cooperative  or  engag- 
ing in  business  affairs  themselves.  After  four  years  of  debate 
in  the  Assembly,  the  central-bank  idea  was  discarded  and  the 
law  of  1894  was  adopted  which  has  forever  given  a  syndical 
cast  and  character  to  agricultural  cooperativie  credit  in 
France. 

This  law,  enacted  through  the  influence  of  MM.  Meline 
and  Albert  Viger,  the  latter  several  times  Minister  of  Agricul- 
ture, is  the  true  charter  of  agricultural  cooperative  credit  in 
France.  According  to  its  provisions  the  cooperative  credit 
societies  have  been  made  adjuncts  of  the  syndicats,  that  is, 


AGRICtTLTUEAL   CEEDIT   IN   FRANCE      333 

they  may  be  formed  only  by  all  or  a  part  of  the  members  of 
one  or  more  than  one  agricultural  professional  syndicat,  and 
only  for  tlie  purpose  of  facilitating  and  guaranteeing  opera- 
tions relating  to  agriculture  carried  on  by  such  syndicat  or 
syndicats  or  members.  By  a  law  of  January  14,  1908,  how- 
ever, members  of  agricultural  mutual  insurance  associations 
were  empowered  to  form  credit  societies. 

The  first  syndicdl  banks  or  credit  societies  for  agricul- 
tural credit  which  appeared  under  the  1894  law  were  those 
founded  by  Jean-Baptiste  Josseau  at  Coulommiers  and  by 
Emile  Duport  under  the  auspices  of  the  syndicat  of  Belle- 
sur-Saone.  In  order  to  hasten  the  movement,  Eugene  Eos- 
tand,  president  of  the  Savings  Bank  des  Bouches-du-Eh6ne, 
with  the  assistance  of  M.  Guillaumont  obtained  the  passage 
of  a  law  in  1895  authorizing  all  savings  banks,  xmder  certain 
conditions,  to  invest  the  entire  revenues  from  their  capital 
stocks  and  one-fifth  of  these  funds  in  loans  to  agricultural  co- 
operative societies  or  in  discountiug  their  paper.  Within  two 
years  thereafter  there  were  75  banks  operating  under  the  1894 
law,  and  at  least  one  hundred  imder  the  1867  law,  while 
448,495  farmers  were  combined  in  1,499  syndicats  organized 
xmder  the  1884  law,  mainly  for  making  collective  purchases  of 
fertilizer  and  feed.  All  this  good  work  was  done  practically 
within  13  years  on  the  private  initiative  of  the  farmers  them- 
selves. But  the  progress  was  not  rapid  enough  to  satisfy  the 
cooperative  enthusiasts,  particularly  in  the  matter  of  credit. 
Without  taking  the  farmers  into  their  councils  or  considering 
the  gravity  of  the  step,  they  decided  to  appeal  to  the  state 
for  assistance,  to  hasten  the  realization  of  their  ambitions  for 
cooperation. 

The  opportunity  came  with  the  debate  on  the  renewal  of 
the  privileges  of  the  Bank  of  France.  This  great  national 
institution  was  founded  in  1803,  placed  imder  the  control 
of  the  state,  and  given  a  monopoly  of  issuing  notes  payable 
at  sight  to  bearer.  '  Its  primary  objects  were  to  assist  industry 
and  commerce  and  to  take  care  of  the  financial  needs  of  the 
state,  but  from  an  early  date  it  had  upon  its  own  initiative 
placed  its  services  at  the  disposal  of  agriculture.     It  had 


334  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

helped  the  agricultural  syndicats  to  form  credit  societies 
and  also  had  supplied  iadividual  fanners  directly  with  funds 
for  fattening  cattle  for  the  market.  The  loans  for  this  pur- 
pose made  between  1867  and  1880  through  the  various 
branches  of  the  Bank  totaled  over  $38,000,000.  As  the 
profits  were  $5,000,000  and  no  losses  had  been  suffered,  the 
Bank  considered  that  farmers  were  safe  and  profitable  cus- 
tomers and  gradually  extended  its  business  with  them.  It 
had,  in  fact,  become  the  greatest  single  factor  in  agricul- 
tural finance  and  it  was  putting  itself  in  the  way  of  gaining 
continuing  and  handsome  profits  therefrom.  Consequently, 
leaders  in  the  Assembly  thought  that  the  Bank  of  France 
should  be  compelled  to  pay  tribute  to  agriculture,  and  they 
planned  to  bring  this  about  upon  the  renewal  of  its  note-issu- 
ing privilege,  which  was  to  expire  in  1897.  The  socialists 
proposed  either  that  $12,000,000  of  the  reserves  of  the  Bank 
of  France  should  be  appropriated  for  creating  a  central  agri- 
cultural bank,  or  else  that  the  Bank  of  Fraaice  should  turn 
over  to  the  state  $100,000,000  to  be  lent  at  low  interest 
rates  to  farmers.  These  projects  were  championed  by  strong 
men.  But  the  disaster  which  overtook  the  first  central  agri- 
cultural bank  in  1876  was  still  fresh  in  memory.  More- 
over, many  realized  that  the  discount  rates  of  the  Bank  of 
France  would  probably  have  to  be  raised  if  a  large  portion 
of  its  ready  cash  were  tied  up  for  the  length  of  time  re- 
quired for  agricultural  loans,  and  saner  views  at  last  pre- 
vailed. 

Accordingly,  on  October  31,  1896,  the  Bank  of  France  in 
consideration  of  having  its  privileges  renewed  until  the  end 
of  1930  agreed  to  make  a  loan  to  the  Government  of  40,000,- 
000  francs  ($8,000,000)  to  run  to  that  date  without  interest. 
The  law  of  November  17,  1897,  ratifying  this  agreement 
provided  that  the  Bank  of  France  should  also  pay  annually  to 
the  state  during  this  entire  period  a  royalty  on  its  operations 
so  calculated  that  the  amount  for  each  year  should  never  fall 
below  3,000,000  francs,  and  that  this  money  also  should  be 
devoted  to  agricidture.  The  law  further  required  the  Bank 
to  discount  the  bills  of  exchange  and  negotiable  instruments 


AGEICULTUEAL   CEEDIT   IN   FRANCE      335 

Bubscribed  or  indorsed  by  agrieultuTal  syndicats  and  all  other 
persons  kaown  to  be  solvent.  The  royalty  was  determined 
at  first  by  multiplying  the  productive  circulation  of  the 
Bank  by  one-eighth  of  its  discount  rate.  By  an  amendment 
to  the  law  in  effect  December  20,  1912,  provision  was  made 
that  when  the  rate  of  discount  shall  have  been  in  excess  of 
four  per  cent  during  any  given  period,  the  percentage  used  for 
calculating  the  royalty  shall  be  raised  for  such  period  from 
one-eighth  to  one-sixth.  Between  1897  and  1913  the  Bank 
of  France  has  advanced  250,000,000  francs  to  agriciiltural  co- 
operative banks  and  576,000,000  francs  to  farmers  directly, 
which,  added  to  the  loan  and  royalties  paid  to  the  state, 
make  a  total  of  one  billion  of  francs  or  about  $200,000,000 
in  15  years  for  the  use  of  agriculture. 

At  the  time  the  privilege  of  the  Bank  of  France  was 
renewed,  legislation  was  devised  for  the  purpose  of  provid- 
ing the  machinery  for  distributing  among  the  farmers  the 
loan  and  royalties  which  had  been  exacted  from  it.  This 
legislation,  drafted  by  M.  Jules  Meline,  was  placed  on  the 
statute  books  through  the  combined  influence  of  himself  and 
Senator  Albert  Viger  on  March  31,  1899.  The  Meline  law, 
as  it  is  called,  has  brought  about  the  creation  of  the  most 
symmetrical  system  of  agricultural  cooperative  banks  and 
credit  societies  existing  in  any  country.  While  it  is  aided 
and  at  present  practically  supported  by  the  state,  its  avowed 
purpose  is  to  stimulate  the  private  initiative  of  the  farmers, 
and  when  this  temporary  assistance  has  accomplished  its 
work  and  been  finally  withdrawn,  France  hopes  to  have  a  per- 
fect machinery  for  financing  agriculture. 

The  Meline  law  provides  that  regional  agricultural  coop- 
erative banks  shall  be  founded  according  to  the  regulations  of 
the  law  of  1894,  with  powers  of  assisting  and  facilitating 
operations  relating  to  agricultural  production  carried  on  by 
members  of  the  local  cooperative  credit  societies  within  their 
prescribed  territories  and  guaranteed  by  such  societies.  The 
regional  banks  are  authorized  to  discount  the  negotiable  in- 
struments made  by  members  of  the  local  societies  and  in- 
dorsed by  such  societies,  and  also  to  make  loans  to  such 


336  EIJEAL   CREDITS 

societies  for  working  funds.  The  paper  having  thus  three 
signatures,  those  of  the  borrowing  farmer,  the  local  society 
and  the  regional  bank,  is  'Tiankable"  according  to  the  com- 
inercial  and  banking  codes,  and  the  regional  banks  may  re- 
discount it  at  the  Bank  of  France  or  at  any  other  of  the 
"big  credit  institutions  in  France  provided  the  time  is  not 
over  nine  months. 

Although  these  regional  banks  were  devised  for  the  spe- 
cial object  of  distributing  to  the  farmers  the  money  which 
the  state  receives  from  the  Bank  of  France,  they  are  not 
formed  by  the  state.  They  are  private,  voluntary  organiza- 
iions,  but  if  they  desire  to  obtain  state  aid  they  must  place 
themselves  under  the  control  of  the  Government.  This  con- 
trol is  exercised  by  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  through  the 
bureau  composed  of  public  officials  which  is  charged  with 
the  distribution  of  the  loan  and  royalties  received  from  the 
Bank  of  France.  By  a  law  of  December  35,  1900,  each 
xegional  bank  may  receive  out  of  these  funds  a  five-year 
loan  without  interest  equal  to  four  times  its  paid-up  capital. 
By  a  law  of  December  29,  1906,  one-third  of  the  royalties 
may  be  used  for  loans  through  the  regional  banks  to  coopera- 
tive societies  organized  for  the  production,  manufacture  or 
sale  of  agricultural  products,  or  for  carrying  on  any  agri- 
■cultural  enterprise  in  common.  But  every  such  society  must 
be  affiliated  with  a  local  credit  society,  and  no  loan  may  run 
for  longer  than  25  years  to  be  larger  than  twice  its  paid-up 
capital.  Finally,  by  a  law  of  March  19,  1910,  loans  may  be 
made  without  interest  and  for  20  years  to  the  regional  banks 
up  to  double  the  amount  of  their  paid-up  capital  to  be  used 
exclusively  in  helping  farmers  to  acquire  or  improve  small 
homesteads.  No  loan  to  any  individual'  farmer  may  exceed 
8,000  francs  ($1,600)  or  run  for  longer  than  15  years.  It 
must  be  repayable  by  instalments  or  annuities  and  be  se- 
cured either  by  a  mortgage  on  the  property  or  by  an  insur- 
ance policy  on  the  life  of  the  borrower.  Land-credit  societies 
created  conformably  to  a  law  of  April  10,  1908,  also  may 
receive  advances  from  the  state  for  this  purpose  in  the  same 
way  as  the  regional  banks. 


AGEICULTUEAL    CKEDIT  ,  IN    FEANCE      337 

The  first  regional  bank  to  be  established  was  La  Caisse 
Eegionale  de  TEst,  formed  by  Mr.  M61ine  on  June  29,  1899, 
less  than  three  months  after  the  law  regarding  such  institu- 
tions was  placed  on  the  statute  book.  In  two  years  there 
were  seven.  By  1904  the  nimiber  began  to  steadily  increase 
under  the  stimulation  of  free  loans  from  the  state,  and  then 
it  was  that  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  established  a  bureau 
for  their  supervision  and  control.  Now  there  exist  practi- 
cally all  the  regional  banks  that  are  needed.  Thus  the  Gov- 
ernment has  accomplished  within  15  years  and  by  advancing- 
large  sums  of  money  its  long  cherished  object  of  having  a 
great  agricultural  credit  system  embracing  the  entire  nation 
and  available  for  all  farmers  belonging  to  syndical  associa- 
tions or  cooperative  societies.  At  the  base  of  this  system, 
called  the  "Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,"  are  the  local  credit 
societies.  Above  them  and  largely  formed  by  them  are  the 
regional  banks,  and  over  all  of  the  latter  which  receive  aid 
from  the  state  is  the  Bureau  of  Supervision  and  Control  of 
the  Ministry  of  Agriculture,  placing  them  in  touch  with  the 
Bank  of  France,  while  assisting  this  Bureau  for  propaganda 
and  organization  work  is  the  Central  Federation  of  Agricul- 
tural Syndicats  of  France.  And  this  system  is  doing  another 
great  work  in  addition  to  improving  credit  facilities  for  farm- 
ers. It  is  gradually  bringing  all  the  agricultural  coopera- 
tive associations  in  France  together  in  a  solid  league  for 
mutual  self-help,  since  under  the  1894  law  as  amended  the 
local  credit  societies  may  be  formed  only  by  members  of  syn- 
dicats and  of  mutual  societies.  That  is  to  say,  the  syndicats 
form  the  credit  societies  as  well  as  the  associations  for  other 
cooperative  purposes,  and  the  syndicats  then  form  themselves 
into  unions  which  are  united  to  the  Central  Federation. 

The  requirements  provided  by  law  for  forming  and  oper- 
ating these  credit  institutions  are  very  simple.  Before  begin- 
ning business  articles  of  agreement  must  be  made  out  in 
duplicate,  with  lists  of  officers,  directors  and  members  show- 
ing full  names,  vocations,  residences  and  the  number  of  shares 
subscribed  by  each.  One  copy  must  be  filed  with  the  justice 
of  the  peace  of  the  canton  in  which  the  credit  society  intends 


338  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

to  have  its  headquarters.  The  other  copy  miist  be  filed  with 
the  tribunal  of  commerce  of  the  assembly  district  in  which 
the  canton  is  situated.  Before  February  15  of  each  year 
similar  statements  must  be  filed  ia  the  same  places  with  a 
brief  account  of  the  receipts  and  expenditures  as  weU  as  of 
the  operations  of  the  preceding  year,  which  are  open  to  ia- 
spection  by  all  who  wish  to  see  them.  Officers  are  per- 
sonally responsible  for  any  damages  resulting  from  violations 
of  the  law  and  are  subject  to  a  fine  not  to  exceed  $100  for 
any  false  entries  in  the  articles  of  agreement.  The  articles 
must  designate  the  headquarters  and  the  manner  of  conduct- 
ing business,  and  show  how  the  capital  is  to  be  formed  and 
the  proportion  that  each  member  must  contribute  to  it.  The 
capital  may  be  formed  only  by  subscriptions  by  persons  who 
are  already  members  of  some  agricultural  professional  syri/- 
dicat  or  agricultural  cooperative  insurance  association. 
Shares  may  be  of  equal  or  unequal  value,  but  they  must  be 
made  out  ia  the  name  of  the  owner  and  cannot  be  transferred 
except  with  the  consent  of  the  society  and  then  only  to 
another  member.  Their  size  is  usually  $4  to  $8,  so  that 
the  poorest  farmers  may  join.  No  society  may  begin  busi- 
ness until  at  least  one-fourth  of  the  subscribed  capital  has 
been  paid  up.  In  case  the  capital  is  variable  it  cannot  be 
reduced  below  the  original  amount  named  in  the  articles 
of  agreement.  The  articles  must  also  specify  the  maximum 
of  deposits  that  may  be  received,  and  determine  the  liability 
of  members,  which  may  be  either  limited  or  unlimited  but  in 
every  event  must  continue  until  all  obligations  contracted  by 
the  society  before  their  withdrawal  have  been  settled. 

The  articles  must  define  the  methods  to  be  used  for  the 
distribution  of  profits.  The  surplus,  after  paying  running 
expenses  and  interest  on  deposits  or  on  whatever  loans  have 
been  contracted,  must  be  set  aside  each  year  up  to  at  least 
three-fourths  for  the  creation  of  a  reserve  until  such  reserve 
equals  one-half  of  the  capital.  Dividends,  in  the  strict  legal 
meaning  of  that  term,  may  not  be  declared,  but  any  balance 
existing  at  the  end  of  the  year  may  be  prorated  among  the 
syndicais  and  among  the  members  of  the  syndicats  in  the 


AGEICULTUEAL    CEEDIT    IN    PEANCE      339 

form  of  rebates  on  their  payments  for  transactions  carried 
on  for  them.  On  dissolution  the  reserves  and  other  assets 
shall  be  distributed  among  the  members  in  proportion  to  the 
amounts  paid  on  their  subscriptions,  unless  the  articles  pre- 
scribe some  other  method  of  disposal  for  an  agricultural 
purpose.  The  credit  societies  are  subject  to  the  regulations 
of  the  commercial  code  and  must  keep  their  accounts  and 
books  according  thereto,  but  they  are  exempt  from  certain 
license  taxes  and  stamp  duties. 

The  powers  of  a  local  credit  society  thus  formed  are  to 
receive  deposits  with  or  without  interest;  to  make  short- 
term  loans  for  distinctly  agricultural  purposes;  to  accept  or 
discount  agricultural  paper;  to  rediscoimt  such  paper  at  a 
regional  bank;  to  make  long-term  loans  out  of  moneys  re- 
ceived imder  the  law  of  March  19,  1910;  to  pay  out  and 
collect  money  on  account  of  their  customers;  to  contract 
loans  necessary  for  creating  or  increasing  their  working 
funds;  and  to  invest  their  idle  funds  in  government  or  mu- 
nicipal bonds,  in  stock  of  the  Bank  of  France  or  of  railroads 
guaranteed  by  the  state,  or  in  debentures  of  the  Credit  Pon- 
der. The  reserves  may  be  kept  at  a  regional  bank  or  at  a 
public  savings  bank. 

The  supreme  authority  of  a  local  credit  society  is  lodged 
in  the  members  regularly  assembled.  Each  member  has  as 
many  votes  as  he  has  shares  and  may  vote  them  by  proxy, 
but  usually  the  maximum  of  the  votes  of  an  individual  mem- 
ber is  limited  to  four  or  five  regardless  of  the  number  of 
his  shares.  Each  year  the  members  elect  two  supervisors 
to  report  on  the  condition  of  the  society  at  the  annual  meet- 
ing of  the  following  year.  They  also  £11  the  vacancies  in 
the  board  of  directors,  one-third  or  one-fourth  of  whom  are 
retired  each  year.  The  board  of  directors  elects  the  presi- 
dent and  vice-presidents  and  the  secretary-treasurer.  The 
latter  official  and  the  managing  director  alone  may  receive 
salaries.  The  board  of  directors  must  aU  be  members  of  the 
society,  and  they  manage  its  affairs  always  by  a  majority 
vote. 

The  office  of  the  society  is  ordinarily  opened  once  a  week. 


340  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

usually  on  Sundays  or  market  days.  The  rate  of  interest  on 
the  long-time  loans  made  with  money  received  from  the  state 
to  enable  farmers  to  buy  or  improve  small  homesteads  is 
determined  by  the  Ministry  of  Agriculture.  The  rate  on 
short-term  loans,  however,  depends  on  the  condition  of  the 
money  market;  at  present  it  is  about  four  per  cent,  and  it  is 
always  at  least  one  per  cent  higher  than  the  discount  rate 
of  the  regional  banks.  The  law  does  not  restrict  the  local 
societies  to  lending  to  members  only;  they  may  lend  to  any 
farmer  who  needs  money  for  an  agricultural  purpose,  but 
only  the  paper  of  a  member  may  be  discounted  at  the  re- 
gional bank.  They  may  lend  also  to  agriciiltural  syndicats, 
agricultural  mutual  insurance  societies  and  agricultural  co- 
operative associations  organized  for  the  purchase,  manufac- 
ture or  sale  of  agricultural  supplies  and  products.  No  limit 
has  been  prescribed  by  law  as  to  the  size  or  length  of  the 
short-term  loans.  In  some  of  the  societies  the  size  is  pro- 
portioned to  the  sums  paid  up  by  the  borrowing  member  on 
his  shares,  and  may  not  exceed  10,  15  or  30  times  that 
amount;  in  others  the  maximum  is  fixed  between  $200  and 
$400,  but  in  every  case  the  credit  rests  upon  the  character 
of  the  borrower,  and  no  person,  no  matter  how  well-to-do, 
can  get  a  loan  unless  his  reputation  for  industry  and  honesty 
is  good.  The  loans  generally  run  for  three  months,  with 
right  to  one,  two  or  three  renewals. 

The  loans  are  made  on  promissory  notes,  bills  of  ex- 
change or  some  form  of  negotiable  instrument,  and  an  in- 
dorsement by  a  responsible  party  or  security  in  the  way  of 
collateral  or  chattel  mortgage  is  always  required.  The 
4,204  local  credit  societies  of  the  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel  in 
1912  had  altogether  215,695  members.  The  subscribed  cap- 
ital was  $4,101,586,  of  which  $2,704,310  had  been  paid  up. 
The  reserves  were  $566,393,  and  the  short-term  loans  out- 
standing at  the  end  of  the  year  amounted  to  $12,964,531. 
The  outstanding  long-term  loans  to  cooperative  societies 
under  the  1906  law  amounted  to  $517,575,  while  the  out- 
standing long-term  loans  to  farmers  on  their  homesteads 
under  the  1910  law  amounted  to  $1,544,399.    Nearly  2,050 


AGEICULTIJEAL   CEEDIT    IN   FEANCE      341 

farmers  have  so  far  taken  advantage  of  this  lav,  and  the 
average  loan  received  from  the  state  was  $745  for  each  in- 
dividual. 

The  local  banks  so  organized  out  of  the  syndicats  and 
insurance  societies  are  thus  the  base  of  the  system.  There  is 
no  restriction  as  to  the  number  which  may  exist  in  any  given 
territory.  They  do  not  receive  any  direct  aid  from  the  state, 
which  is  granted  only  to  the  regional  banks.  As  soon  as 
the  board  of  directors  of  a  local  credit  society  is  elected,  it 
proceeds  to  the  selection  of  the  ofiBcers.  The  president  there- 
upon requests  affliation  of  the  new  bank  with  the  regional 
bank  of  its  department  and  delivers  to  it  a  copy  of  its  by- 
laws and  a  list  of  members,  officers  and  supervisors.  In 
order  to  effect  mutuality  between  the  two,  the  local  bank 
should  subscribe  to  some  shares  of  the  regional  bank.  The 
number  is  not  prescribed  and  varies  vrith  its  available  re- 
sources. 

The  regional  banks  are  similar  in  organization  and  ad- 
ministration to  the  local  credit  societies,  since  both  must 
be  formed  under  the  1894  law,  but  by  a  provision  of  the 
1899  law  the  articles  of  agreement  of  a  regional  bank  must 
define  the  area  of  its  operation  and  specify  the  amount  of 
its  capital  and  number  of  its  shares,  two-thirds  of  which  at 
least  must  be  offered  to  local  credit  societies  for  subscription. 
Dividends  may  not  exceed  five  per  cent  per  year.  A  regional 
bank  when  thus  duly  formed  may  discount  the  negotiable 
instruments  of  members  of  local  credit  societies  within  its 
territory  upon  the  indorsement  of  such  societies;  and  it  is 
authorized  also  to  make  loans  to  such  societies;  out  of  the 
funds  received  from  the  state  to  make  advances  to  such  so- 
cieties for  them  in  their  turn  to  lend  at  long  term  for  creat- 
ing or  improving  small  homesteads  according  to  the  1910 
law;  to  receive  deposits;  to  issue  notes  up  to  an  amount  not 
exceeding  three-fourths  of  the  value  of  the  securities  which 
it  has  on  hand;  to  rediscount  aU  its  bankable  paper;  to 
invest  its  idle  funds  in  the  same  way  as  a  local  credit  society 
and  to  receive  money  from  the  state  for  lending  at  long  term  to 
cooperative  societies  according  to  the  1906  law;  and  it  is 


343  EUEAL    CREDITS 

especially  charged  with  the  supervision  of  the  local  credit 
societies  aflSliated  ■with  it. 

All  regional  banks  which  receive  money  from  the  state 
are  subject  to  the  supervision  of  the  Ministry  of  Agriculture 
and  must  keep  their  books  and  accounts  in  accordance  with 
the  rules  and  regulations  prescribed.  They  must  submit 
financial  statements  to  it  four  times  a  year  and  annually 
they  are  examined  by  a  government  inspector.  They  cannot 
affiliate  with  local  credit  societies  organized  on  the  unlimited- 
liability  plan  because  such  concerns  have  no  funds  with  which 
to  buy  shares,  nor  are  they  permitted  to  do  business  with 
any  society  which  is  not  exclusively  agricultural  or  which  pays 
to  members  as  dividends  more  than  five  per  cent  a  year  on 
its  capital.  The  regional  banks  endeavor  to  be  as  large  as 
possible  for  the  reason  that  the  amount  of  the  money  they 
may  receive  from  the  state  depends  upon  the  size  of  their 
capital.  In  1912  the  98  regional  banks  reeeiviag  aid  from 
the  state  had  a  combined  capital  subscribed  of  $4,666,068, 
of  which  $4,310,244  had  been  paid  in,  $2,782,039  having  been 
contributed  by  the  local  credit  societies.  The  reserves  were 
$1,242,595.  They  had  taken  in  $4,007,219  of  deposits.  The 
total  of  their  discounts  and  renewals  for  the  year  was  $36,- 
523,760,  while  the  loans  to  the  local  credit  societies  for  vari- 
ous purposes  outstanding  at  the  end  of  the  year  amounted 
to  $12,677,602,  and  to  agricultural  syndicats,  cooperative 
associations  and  mutual  insurance  societies  to  $2,886,800. 
The  discount  rate  of  only  two  of  the  banks  was  less  than 
that  of  the  Bank  of  France.  The  general  expenses  of  all  these 
regional  banks  amounted  to  only  $102,406,  showiug  that  they 
are  run  economically  and  with  comparatively  little  expense. 

The  total  amount  of  the  debt  of  this  system  of  rural  co- 
operative banks  to  the  state  is  now  $17,177,745.  This  has 
all  come  from  the  Bank  of  France.  The  law  of  1899,  enacted 
for  the  distribution  of  the  Bank's  loan  and  royalties,  had 
at  first  in  view  only  loans  to  individual  farmers  at  short 
term  and  provided  that  advances  should  be  made  to  the 
regional  banks  without  interest  for  five  years  with  renewals 
if  necessary  for  making  loans  to  or  discounting  the  paper  of 


AGEICIJLTUEAL   CEBDIT   IN   FEANCE      343 

members  of  the  local  credit  societies.  But  the  scope  of  the 
system  was  gradually  extended.  In  1906  a  law  was  passed 
for  organizing  collective  credit  at  long  term  whereby  one- 
third  of  the  royalties  of  the  Bank  of  France  were  set  aside 
to  be  loaned  by  the  regional  banks  to  agricidtural  coopera- 
tive societies  for  25  years  at  two  per  cent  per  annum  with 
amortization.  Finally,  in  1910  long-term  individual  credit 
for  individuals  was  organized  by  a  law  whereby  the  regional 
banks  were  required  to  use  two-thirds  of  the  royalties  for 
making  8,000-francs  ($1,600)  15-year  reducible  loans  to 
farmers  through  the  local  credit  societies  for  creatiag  small 
homesteads.  Thus  at  present  only  the  $8,000,000  loan  from 
the  Bank  of  France  is  used  for  short-term  loans,  and  by  a 
law  of  1912  the  Government  has  been  authorized  to  take 
$2,400,000  of  this  for  long-term  individual  loans,  to  be  reim- 
bursed out  of  the  royalties  as  they  fall  due.  By  a  law  of 
1910  the  Government  may  advance  six  times  instead  of  four 
times  the  amount  of  the  capital  of  a  regional  bank  in  any 
district  where  the  grape  growers  have  been  afflicted  with  bad 
crops. 

The  loan  of  $8,000,000  which  the  state  received  from  the 
Bank  of  France  must  be  repaid  in  1920.  The  royalties,  which 
in  1913  amounted  to  $17,860,720,  make  a  total  thus  far  of 
$25,860,720  obtained  from  the  bank.  The  royalties  are  in- 
creasing yearly  and  there  is  a  possibility  that  the  state  will 
be  able  to  repay  the  Bank  at  the  appointed  time,  but  it  is 
evident  that  the  rural  credit  system  is  not  yet  self-sustaining 
or  in  a  position  to  meet  its  obligations  to  the  state.  The 
question  is  being  discussed  how  the  system  will  take  care  of 
itself  when  the  assistance  which  was  intended  to  be  temporary 
is  finally  withdrawn.  During  the  first  years  the  Government 
did  not  demand  any  partial  payments  from  the  regional  banks 
on  the  renewals  of  their  loans,  but  during  recent  years  it 
has  exacted  one-fifth  of  one  per  cent  of  the  principal  upon 
renewal.  In  this  way  the  regional  banks  are  gradually  ac- 
customing themselves  to  looking  elsewhere  for  working  funds. 

There  are  four  natural  sources  from  which  these  may  be 
drawn.     The  first  is  from  deposits,  but  deposits  are  com- 


344  KUEAL    CREDITS 

paratively  small  at  present.  The  second  is  by  the  increase  of 
their  share  capital,  but  dividends  would  have  to  be  allowed 
and  materially  increased  in  order  to  bring  this  about.  The 
third  is  by  loans  from  individuals  or  from  the  savings  banks. 
Many  of  the  latter  institutions  are  owned  by  municipalities 
and  all  are  subject  to  the  control  of  the  Government.  Their 
combined  assets  exceed  $18,000,000,  of  which  $5,000,000,  say- 
ing nothing  of  annual  revenues,  are  available  for  agriculture 
by  the  law  of  1895,  but  very  little  of  them  have  been  used 
yet  for  this  purpose.  The  fourth  is  by  short-term  bonds  of 
the  regional  banks,  provision  for  which  was  made  by  the 
law  of  1899.  No  bonds  have  yet  been  issued,  but  they  might 
be  made  an  effective  means  of  financing  the  agricultural 
mutual  credit  system  provided  safeguards  are  thrown  aroimd 
their  issue.  Until  deposits  begin  to  be  attracted  in  suffi- 
cient volume  for  their  transactions,  the  regional  banks  proba- 
bly will  depend  upon  the  two  latter  sources  after  state  aid 
is  withdrawn,  although  the  plan  of  establishing  a  central 
bank  to  take  the  place  of  the  state  is  favored  in  many  quar- 
ters and  even  by  the  Government. 

Nothing,  however,  has  yet  come  to  light  to  enable  a  fore- 
cast to  be  made  of  the  direction  which  future  development 
will  take.  Indeed  the  future  is  very  uncertain.  State  aid 
which  has  been  so  lavishly  extended  lq  France  has  registered 
a  conspicuous  failure  when  considered  from  the  viewpoint 
of  the  hopes  entertained  in  1899.  Even  its  partisans  are  far 
from  satisfied  with  the  progress  made,  and  are  now  contem- 
plating amendments  to  the  laws  in  order  to  bring  about  vital 
changes  in  the  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel.  To  say  nothing  of 
the  dependence  upon  funds  officially  supplied,  the  intimate 
relations  between  the  system  and  the  Government  bind  to- 
gether the  financial  destinies  of  both.  The  occurrence  of  a 
great  war,  for  instance,  which  only  served  to  prove  the  abso- 
lute solidity  of  the  self-reliant  German  system  in  1870,  might 
imperil  the  very  existence  of  this  French  state-aided  system. 
No  one  can  foretell,  of  course,  what  will  happen,  but  per- 
haps, as  the  years  roll  on,  larger  numbers  of  members  of  the 
Credit  Agricole  Mutuel  will  appreciate  the  value  of  the  prin- 


AGEICITLTUEAL    CEEDIT    IN    FEANCE      345 

ciples  of  seK-help  maintained  by  the  Federation  of  the 
Farmers'  and  Workmen's  Banks  with  Unlimited  Liability 
and,  in  a  lesser  degree,  by  the  Central  Federation,  and  then 
the  full  meed  of  praise  will  be  bestowed  upon  Eostand,  Eay- 
neri  and  especially  upon  Louis  Durand,  who  for  over  a 
generation  have  been  fighting  the  good  fight  for  mutual 
self-help  and  pure  cooperation. 


CHAPTEE   XXV 

ITALY:   LtrZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG 

Luzzatti  and  His  Cooperative  Credit  Bank. — Departures  from  the 
Schulze-Delitzseh  and  Eaiffeisen  Systems. — ^Legislation. — Man- 
agement.— Business. — Wollemborg  and  Rural  Credit  Societies. — 
National  Federation  of  Rural  Credit  Societies. — Position  of 
the  Church. — Success  of  the  Associations. — Special  Laws  for 
the  South. — Government  Aid. — Casse  Ademprivili  of  Sardinia. — 
Central  Banks  versus  Local  Organizations. 

The  honor  of  the  establishment  of  cooperative  credit  in 
Italy  is  due  to  Luigi  Lnzzatti  and  Leone  Wollemborg,  two 
illustrious  Jews,  whose  unselfish  work,  begun  early  in  life, 
has  been  rendered  doubly  effective  by  the  sympathy  and  sup- 
port of  the  Catholic  Church  and  the  state.  Both  came  from 
wealthy  families,  were  finely  educated,  had  precocious  abil- 
ities as  writers,  orators  and  organizers,  and  have  held  high 
positions  in  the  civil  government.  Luzzatti  has  been  several 
times  Minister  of  Finance,  Minister  of  Agriculture,  Com- 
merce and  Industry,  and  Prime  Minister.  Dr.  Wollemborg 
has  served  in  Parliament  and  has  been  Minister  of  Fi- 
nance. 

These  two  men,  powerful  in  banking  circles  and  politics, 
are  famous  throughout  the  cooperative  world,  the  first  for 
having  originated  a  new  type  of  people's  bank,  and  the  second 
for  having  implanted  a  system  of  rural  credits  which  was 
thought  to  be  inadaptable  to  Italian  conditions.  When  they 
began  their  work,  the  laborers  and  farmers  in  many  parts 
of  Italy  were  sunk  in  dull  apathy  because  of  rapacious  usury 
and  had  sullenly  reconciled  themselves  to  extortionate  de- 
mands of  their  landlords  as  well  as  the  money  lenders.  Lit- 
tle cash  was  available.     Interest  rates  reached  the  highest 

346 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLiLEMBOKG     347 

point  on  record  and  supplies  were  bought  at  ruinous  prices. 
As  typical  of  the  prevailing  situation  Sir  Frederick  A.  Nich- 
olson mentions  the  instance  of  a  ring  formed  in  Abario  to 
squeeze  the  last  cent  out  of  the  impoverished  population. 
These  usurers  sold  $10  worth  of  corn  for  $30  on  three  months' 
time.  This  meant  interest  at  the  rate  of  400  per  cent,  while 
for.  small  loans  the  usurers  exacted  1,200  per  cent  payable 
in  advance,  besides  commissions,  with  possibly  dinner  and 
wine  for  the  lender  and  broker. 

Aroused  by  the  sight  of  such  wrongs  practised  even  within 
the  precincts  of  the  great  savings  banks  and  charitable  lend- 
ing institutions  which  abounded  in  Italy,  Luzzatti  in  1864, 
then  only  23  years  of  age,  made  a  trip  to  Germany  to  study 
cooperation.  Fired  by  the  teachings  of  Sehulze-Delitzsch,  on 
his  return  home  he  wrote  a  monograph,  now  classic,  on  the 
diffusion  of  credit,  and  he  continued  to  advance  his  ideas 
on  this  subject  in  the  University  of  Padua  in  which  he  had 
been  made  a  professor  of  political  economy.  But  he  shortly 
deserted  scholastic  for  political  life,  and  soon  began  to  make 
a  practical  application  of  the  principles  which  he  had 
evolved. 

On  May  25,  1866,  Luzzatti  opened  at  MUan  the  first 
cooperative  credit  bank  in  Italy.  Its  capital  was  only  $140, 
of  which  he  contributed  $20,  thus  becoming  the  heaviest 
shareholder.  It  employed  no  paid  oflBcers  or  clerks,  and 
Luzzatti  himself  did  all  the  work,  receiving  the  fimds  which 
came  in  and  attending  to  the  loans  while  seated  at  a  desk 
on  the  sidewalk  in  front  of  its  humble  office,  much  to  the 
amusement  of  his  rich  friends,  who  were  utterly  unable  to 
understand  the  purpose  of  his  course  or  to  appreciate  the 
great  possibilities  which  lay  in  the  idea  he  had  conceived. 
To-day  this  People's  Bank  of  Milan  has  grown  to  be  one  of 
the  largest  moneyed  institutions  in  Italy.  It  is  lodged  in  a 
palatial  office  building  and  has  about  70  unpaid  officers  and 
more  than  100  paid  clerks.  In  1909  the  number  of  its 
members  was  24,774.  Its  capital  was  $1,923,910,  divided 
into  192,391  shares,  and  back  of  this  was  a  reserve  of  $961,- 
955.    Its  deposits,  savings  and  ordinary,  were  $32,729,874, 


348  ETJKAL   CEEDITS 

and  its  turnover  of  business  amounted  to  $535,693,455.  Upon 
this  it  realized  a  profit  of  $306,235,  which  enabled  it  to  dis- 
tribute a  dividend  at  the  rate  of  7.20  per  cent  on  the  50-lire 
($10)  share  after  paying  its  relatively  small  managerial  ex- 
penses, amounting  to  $92,444,  taxes,  etc.,  and  setting  aside 
a  liberal  sum  for  charity. 

Besides  rising  to  this  high  eminence  from  its  unpreten- 
tious beginnings  48  years  ago,  the  People's  Bank  of  Milan 
has  served  as  a  model  for  735  similar  banks,  which  had,  in 
1908,  501,032  members.  Their  capital  and  reserves  amounted 
to  $31,132,800,  and  their  deposits  to  $200,000,000,  while 
their  total  turnover  exceeded  $320,000,000.  About  $100,- 
000,000  of  the  turnover  represented  loans  to  farmers.  The 
older  of  these  banks  belong  to  a  federation  organized  by 
Luzzatti  in  1876  with  headquarters  at  Eome,  and  most  of 
them  are  loosely  grouped  around  nine  of  the  largest  banks. 
The  People's  Bank  of  Milan  does  business  with  about  300  of 
them.  But  they  are  not  bound  by  contract  or  made  subject 
by  law  to  inspection  or  audit  by  any  higher  supervising  au- 
thority, and  hence  do  not  constitute  a  system,  properly 
so-called. 

The  people's  banks  of  Italy  are  likened  to  the  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  banks  of  Germany,  but  although  based  on  the 
same  general  principles  there  are  fundamental  points  of 
difference  between  the  two.  When  Luzzatti  made  his  trip  to 
Germany  in  1864,  both  Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Eaiffeisen  were 
preaching  unlimited  liability.  Eealizing  that  such  a  plan 
would  not  be  acceptable  to  Italians,  Luzzatti  formed  his 
bank  at  Milan  with  limited  liability.  He  did  away  also 
with  Schulze's  large  shares  payable  in  small  instalments  run- 
ning over  long  periods,  and  substituted  in  their  stead  shares 
of  50  lire  ($10)  payable  in  ten  instalments,  thereby  reducing 
the  intake  of  funds  from  this  source.  This  feature  forced  his 
bank  to  depend  mainly  on  deposits  for  carrying  on  its  op- 
erations, and  made  the  capital  a  guarantee  rather  than  a 
working  fund,  which  is  altogether  different  from  the  case 
in  Germany.  Next  Luzzatti  discarded  Schulze's  idea  of  rea- 
sonable salaries  and  compensation  and  required  all  officers  of 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLBMBOEG     349 

his  bank  to  serve  absolutely  without  pay.  Finally  he  enlarged 
the  boards  and  committee  and  even  created  new  ofiBces,  and  by 
thus  providing  for  a  more  numerous  administration  made 
the  management  of  his  bank  very  democratic.  This  has 
residted  in  keeping  the  bank  and  the  members  in  closer 
touch  vrith  one  another,  and  also  has  enabled  the  bank  to 
attend  to  the  needs  of  the  poorer  members  with  greater  safety 
and  to  give  them  more  careful  consideration  than  the  German 
banks  have  found  practicable. 

During  the  early  years  the  people's  banks  of  Italy  en- 
countered a  serious  difficulty  in  the  lack  of  proper  legisla- 
tion. The  essential  feature  of  a  cooperative  society  is  a  vari- 
able capital,  a  capital  susceptible  of  increase  by  successive 
payments  and  the  subscription  of  new  shares  by  the  mem- 
bers or  the  admission  of  new  members,  and  of  decrease  by 
the  withdrawal  in  whole  or  ia  part  of  the  amounts  of  the 
shares.  But  the  Italian  laws  as  they  then  stood  provided  only 
for  fixed  capital.  The  banks  were  compelled  to  form  them- 
selves accordingly,  but  they  managed  to  assimie  a  coopera- 
tive character  by  issuing  new  shares  as  occasion  required  and 
then  having  these  issues  made  legal  at  the  end  of  the  year 
by  voting  an  increase  of  the  capital  stock.  This  irregular 
subterfuge  was  necessary  until  January  1,  1883,  when  a  new 
commercial  code  opened  the  way  for  true  cooperation. 

According  to  this  code,  as  amended  from  time  to  time,  co- 
operative associations  may  be  organized  with  or  without  share 
capital,  and  may  be  based  on  either  limited  or  imlimited  lia- 
bility, or  liability  limited  as  to  some  members  and  unlimited 
as  to  others.  They  may  be  created  by  filing  a  sworn  organiza- 
tion certificate,  which  must  show  the  conditions  for  the  ad- 
mission, withdrawal  and  retirement  of  members,  and  the 
manner  and  times  of  payments  on  shares  subscribed  for.  It 
must  show  also  the  method  of  calling  meetings  of  the  mem- 
bers and  designate  the  newspaper  to  be  used  for  publication 
of  notices,  etc.  If  a  society  has  unlimited  liability,  the  offi- 
cers must  file  at  the  tribunal  of  commerce  every  three  months 
a  list  of  its  members,  showing  all  who  were  admitted  and 
retired  during  that  period.     Shares  having  a  value  of  over 


350  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

$20  cannot  be  issued.  No  one  may  hold  more  than  $1,000 
of  shares,  or  belong  to  two  or  more  credit  societies  at  the 
same  time.  Members  axe  responsible,  according  to  the  form 
of  liability  assumed,  for  all  obligations  contracted  by  a  so- 
ciety up  to  the  day  of  their  retirement,  and  this  liability  lasts 
two  years. 

Such  are  the  main  provisions  of  the  code.  Its  object  was 
to  bring  cooperative  associations  under  the  common  law  and 
to  make  each  amenable  to  the  rules  prescribed  for  its  form. 
Hence  there  is  very  little  difference  between  the  legal  status 
of  a  cooperative  concern  and  one  formed  for  a  purely  lucra- 
tive object.  They  may  be  organized  for  the  same  purposes, 
have  the  same  powers,  and  arrange  by  their  by-laws  all  the 
details  of  their  organization  and  management  subject  to  the 
regulations  of  the  code  and  other  laws  applying  to  both  alike. 
Cooperative  societies  are  exempt  from  certain  taxes  and 
stamp  duties  imder  certain  conditions,  while  savings  banks 
and  mimicipalities  may  deposit  their  funds  with  credit  asso- 
ciations. These  are  the  only  privileges  which  they  have  been 
granted. 

The  people's  banks  governed  by  this  law  have  aU  taken 
the  limited-liability  form,  and  although  there  are  consider- 
able differences  among  them  in  detail  they  are  organized  and 
managed  along  the  same  general  lines.  Since  they  are 
strictly  cooperative,  only  those  features  need  be  referred  to 
which  distinguish  the  Italian  from  the  German  and  French 
types  of  society  already  described. 

The  model  for  by-laws  prepared  by  the  Luzzatti  federa- 
tion shows  that  the  territory  of  operations  is  frequently  so 
extended  that  branches  and  agencies  are  established  to  cover 
it.  Shares  rarely  exceed  $10  or  entrance  fees  $5.  The  value 
of  the  shares  and  the  size  of  the  entrance  fee  for  new  mem- 
bers is  determined  each  year  and  depends  upou  the  amount 
of  paid-in  capital  and  reserves,  the  larger  and  older  banks 
as  a  rule  being  the  more  expensive  to  join.  Similarly,  the 
monthly  instalment  on  shares  and  the  number  a  member  is 
allowed  to  hold  depend  upon  their  value.  In  a  rich  and 
prosperous  bank  the  instalment  may  be  fixed  at  two  lire  (40 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     351 

cents),  and  if  the  share  is  50  lire  the  maximum  for  holdings 
may  he  3,500  lire  ($500).  The  privilege  of  paying  in 
monthly  instalments  is  allowed  only  to  a  person  acquiring 
but  a  single  share.  The  character  of  an  applicant  for  ad- 
mission must  be  indorsed  by  two  members. 

The  annual  meetings  of  the  members  are  held  usually 
in  the  middle  of  March.  Special  meetings  may  be  called  by 
the  proper  officers  or  by  one-tenth  of  the  total  number  of 
members.  One-fifth  of  the  total  number  constitute  a 
quorum.  Officers  cannot  vote  at  these  meetings  on  matters 
relating  to  their  official  acts.  Unless  expressly  permitted  by 
the  by-laws,  voting  by  proxy  is  barred. 

The  supreme  body  in  the  management  is  the  board  of 
directors.  In  small  banks  their  number  is  seven,  and  in  the 
larger  130  to  140.  One-third  of  them  are  renewed  each  year. 
The  chairman  of  the  board  is  the  president  of  the  bank. 
One-half  of  the  body  constitutes  a  quorum,  and  meetings  are 
held  fortnightly.  The  board  may  engage  a  manager  and  a 
cashier  who  upon  appointment  must  enroll  as  members.  It 
may  delegate  its  powers  to  one  or  more  of  its  members,  but 
generally  when  the  board  is  numerous  the  bank  has  a  com- 
mittee of  control  of  five.  No  relative  of  a  director  to  the 
fourth  degree  of  consanguinity  or  affinity  may  be  a  controller. 
To  the  committee  of  control  is  assigned  the  duty  of  auditing 
and  reporting  on  the  annual  balance  sheet  and  exercising  a 
constant  and  effective  supervision  over  the  finances  and  ad- 
ministration of  the  bank.  Members  of  the  committee  take 
weekly  turns,  and  one  of  them  must  be  in.  attendance  at  the 
bank  each  day. 

The  discount  committee  consists  of  at  least  five,  and  in 
the  larger  banks  of  15  to  40  members,  who  remain  in  office 
for  two  years.  They  meet  each  week.  Jointly  with  two  or 
more  of  the  directors  designated  by  the  president,  for  passing 
upon  the  applications  for  loans,  and  no  loan  may  be  granted 
or  bill  discounted  except  with  the  approval  of  a  majority. 
One  of  the  special  duties  of  this  committee  is  to  prepare  and 
revise  a  register  or  card  list  showing  the  credit  standing  of 
each  member.     If  a  borrower  fails  to  perform  his  engage- 


353  EUEAL    CEBDITS 

ments,  or  if  his  security  depreciates  ten  per  cent,  or  if  his 
own  rating  falls  below  the  estimate  on  the  register,  the 
credit  extended  to  him  is  immediately  recalled  unless  he  can 
make  good  the  deficiency.  As  an  adjunct  to  this  committee 
the  larger  banks  have  a  committee  on  risks  to  keep  watch  on 
all  outstanding  loans.  There  is  also  a  committee  on  "honor" 
loans  to  attend  to  members  who  are  so  poor  that  they  cannot 
furnish  security  or  indorsers  but  seek  credit  on  their  char- 
acter alone. 

All  banks  have  a  committee  of  three  arbitrators  elected 
for  three  years,  whose  duty  is  to  decide  cases  carried  to  them 
on  appeal  regarding  the  admission  and  expulsion  of  members 
and  the  refusal  of  credit.  Except  in  the  matter  of  admitting 
new  members,  they  must  act  as  friendly  arbitrators  and  try 
to  assure  every  member  equitable  treatment  at  the  bank. 
Their  decision  is  final  unless  set  aside  at  a  meeting  of  the 
shareholders. 

The  business  of  the  Italian  people's  banks  embraces  all 
kinds  of  banking  transactions.  They  may  receive  deposits 
from  outsiders  and  even  extend  credit  to  non-members  who 
are  in  need  and  worthy  of  their  help.  The  larger  banks  all 
have  special  funds  for  this  benevolence.  Eeal-estate  mort- 
gages are  not  favored  and  collateral  and  pledges  of  personal 
property  are  avoided  as  much  as  possible.  The  indorsement 
of  one  or  two  members  is  the  preferred  security,  for  the 
"capitalization  of  honesty"  has  been  Luzzatti's  watchword 
from  the  beginning.  Cash  credit  is  frequently  practised,  but 
the  acceptance  and  discounting  of  bills  of  exchange  are  the 
modes  of  according  credit  generally  used.  Commercial  bank- 
ing, it  will  be  remembered,  originated  in  Italy,  and  the  hum- 
blest persons  are  familiar  with  banking  paper  and  accus- 
tomed to  use  all  its  various  forms  in  their  transactions. 
Bills,  notes  and  drafts  for  the  smallest  amounts  pass  through 
the  people's  banks.  The  maturity  is  three  months,  with 
privilege  of  renewal  one  or  two  times  upon  making  partial 
payments.  The  maximum  ordinarily  allowed  farmers  is  one 
year.  Except  in  the  case  of  farmers  the  loans  are  not  re- 
quired to  be  employed  for  a  specific  purpose.     The  banks 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG      353 

have  brought  the  interest  rate  on  credit  down  to  7.5  per  cent 
and  in  many  places  to  four  per  cent.  Deposits  draw  three 
to  four  per  cent.  Most  banks  set  aside  25  to  30  per  cent  of 
the  annual  profits  for  the  reserves  until  these  with  the  capital 
give  them  a  fair-sized  working  fund.  The  average  dividend 
on  shares  (1908)  was  8.34  per  cent. 

The  people's  banks  of  Italy  have  not  proved  very  success- 
ful in  helping  poor  persons  without  any  resources  of  their 
own.  In  fact  they  are  not  intended  for  this  class  any  more 
than  are  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  of  Germany.  Their 
clientMe  is  composed  mainly  of  small  merchants,  shop-keep- 
ers, artisans  such  as  tailors,  boot-makers,  etc.,  who  work  on 
their  own  account,  and  all  those  whose  reputation  and  sol- 
vency are  good  yet  have  not  sufScient  business  or  standing 
to  obtain  recognition  at  the  commercial  banks.  According 
to  recent  statistics,  70  per  cent  of  their  money  is  lent  in  sums 
ranging  from  $40  to  $1,000,  13.45  per  cent  in  sums  above 
$1,000,  and  only  17.04  per  cent  in  sums  below  $40.  Nor 
have  the  people's  banks  rendered  as  much  help  to  farmers  as 
was  at  first  expected  of  them,  for  the  reason  that  they  do 
not  find  it  convenient  to  grant  loans  for  the  long  periods 
required  by  agriculture,  or  else  they  obtain  more  profitable 
employment  for  their  funds  in  the  cities. 

Under  a  law  of  1869,  credit  institutions  which  receive  a 
special  license  may  issue  legal-tender  notes  against  certain 
cash  balances.  Under  a  law  of  1887  such  institutions  may 
issue  bonds  for  raising  money  for  use  in  making  loans  se- 
cured by  mortgage  or  on  a  certain  kind  of  land  security 
peculiar  to  Italy.  These  laws  were  enacted  in  behalf  of  agri- 
culture, but  only  a  few  of  the  larger  people's  banks  have 
availed  themselves  of  these  powers  and  their  transactions 
thereunder  have  not  been  very  important.  The  usual  way 
in  which  they  help  the  farming  classes  is  by  making  loans 
to  agricultural  associations  or  rural  credit  societies  or  by 
discounting  the  paper  passed  through  such  concerns.  Most 
of  the  $100,000,000  which  the  people's  banks  claim  to  have 
devoted  to  agriculture  is  represented  by  this  kind  of  busi- 
ness.   Many  of  the  Catholic  banks  formed  on  the  Luzzatti 


354  RTJEAL   CEEDITS 

principles  and  located  in  villages,  however,  have  many  small 
farmers  among  their  members  and  have  proved  themselves 
perfectly  adapted  to  their  needs.  But  vrhatever  may  be  the 
extent  of  the  financial  assistance  which  the  people's  banks 
have  rendered  agriculture,  they  have  always  given  their 
friendly  services  to  strengthen  the  rural  banks  and  increase 
their  number.  This  harmonious  relation  is  in  striking  con- 
trast with  the  situation  in  Germany  where  the  two  systems 
are  practically  opposed  to  one  another. 

An  agitation  for  introducing  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies 
in  Italy  began  as  soon  as  the  enactment  of  the  law  of  1883 
made  the  existence  of  these  little  institutions  possible.  At 
that  time  there  were  139  of  Luzzatti's  banks  in  existence, 
but  only  an  insignificant  part  of  their  114,072  members  were 
farmers.  Usury  was  as  rampant  in  the  fields  as  ever.  Luz- 
zatti,  realizing  that  something  shoiild  be  done  and  well  know- 
ing what  the  remedy  was,  said  in  effect :  "If  the  ardor  of  an 
apostle  were  to  raise  up  banks  similar  to  those  of  Eaiffeisen, 
they  would  be  welcome.  I  will  not  in  Italy  renew  those  useless 
polemics  which  have  disgraced  the  cooperative  movement  in 
Germany.  If  that  apostle  should  not  disdain  to  accept  it,  I 
would  offer  him  my  hand  for  alliance  and  help."  Wollem- 
borg,  then  only  24  years  of  age,  had  been  studying  the  sub- 
ject for  several  years,  and  when  he  heard  Luzzatti's  appeal 
he  replied :  "I  am  he."  Both  have  kept  their  words.  The 
elder  stood  behind  the  younger  man  until  he  had  accom- 
plished his  task,  and  the  two  are  now  recognized  as  the  lead- 
ing exponents  of  cooperative  credit  in  Italy. 

WoUemborg  started  his  first  rural  credit  society  in  Loreg- 
gia,  a  parish  near  Padua.  Everyone  told  him  that  his  experi- 
ment would  be  a  failure,  but  with  the  help  of  the  priest  he 
induced  32  persons  to  join,  and  the  society  was  opened  on  Au- 
gust 13, 1883.  In  18  months  96  more  had  joined,  and  16  had 
gone  out,  of  whom  four  had  died,  six  migrated,  five  vrith- 
drawn,  and  one  had  been  expelled.  At  the  end  of  four  and 
one-half  months  the  society  had  taken  in  $1,400  of  deposits, 
$400  of  which  belonged  to  WoUemborg. 

The  Loreggia  Credit  Society  has  no  shares  or  capital 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     355 

stock.  This  was  according  to  the  original  principle  of  Eaif- 
feisen,  which  could  not  be  carried  out  in  its  purity  in  Ger- 
many where  the  laws  make  share  capital  compulsory.  No 
dividends  are  paid  and  the  whole  of  the  profits  are  turned 
into  the  reserve.  The  reserve  fund  is  owned  absolutely  by 
the  society  itself  and  no  member  has  any  right  in  it.  In 
ease  of  dissolution  it  would  be  placed  in  trust  to  be  held  in- 
tact for  any  new  bank  that  might  be  organized  in  the  vicinity 
on  lines  similar  to  the  one  dissolved. 

The  reserve  is  used  for  covering  losses  and  for  carrying 
on  operations,  and  whenever  it  reaches  a  size  deemed  suffi- 
cient for  these  purposes,  the  annual  proceeds  are  devoted  to 
some  work  of  common  utility.  The  by-laws  expressly  de- 
clare: "The  duty  of  the  society  [is]  to  promote  all  institu- 
tions likely  to  better,  morally  or  materially,  the  condition  of 
the  inhabitants  of  the  village,  and  to  foster  the  foundation 
of  cooperative  associations  for  production,  sale  and  consump- 
tion, by  granting  loans  or  opening  cash  credits  to  persons 
imdertaking  such  enterprises."  AH  loans,  no  matter  what 
their  duration  is  intended  to  be,  are  granted  only  by  succes- 
sive renewals  of  three  months  each.  This  practice  enables 
the  society  to  decline  to  continue  the  credit  should  a  bor- 
rower's standing  or  security  become  impaired;  and  also  to 
encourage  him  to  make  at  regular  intervals  partial  payments 
of  the  money  advanced  to  him. 

Disputes  between  members  are  decided  at  their  meetings ; 
if  they  are  not  settled  there,  three  arbitrators  must  be  selected 
by  the  parties,  in  accordance  with  the  civil  code.  There  is 
also  a  committee  of  five  controllers,  who,  before  the  law  for- 
bade it,  might  be  non-members.  This  arrangement  was  sug- 
gested by  Luzzatti,  who  believes  that  the  management  and 
the  control  of  a  credit  society  should  always  be  kept  separate 
and  distinct.  Thus  the  Loreggia  bank  follows  the  Eaiffeisen 
type,  with  some  important  differences.  It  does  not  teach 
religion,  but  it  requires  all  members  to  know  how  to  read 
and  write.  It  does  not  buy  or  sell  supplies,  and  in  place  of 
long-term  loans  recallable  on  four-weeks'  notice,  it  accords 
short-term  renewable  credit.    It  charges  small  entrance  fees. 


356  EUKAL   CEEDITS 

has  an  extra  body,  the  committee  of  control,  in  its  adminis- 
tration, and  possesses  a  more  ntunerous  committee  of  man- 
agement than  its  German  model.  In  other  respects  they  are 
alike. 

The  Loreggia  Credit  Society  still  remains  small.  It  is 
not  much  larger  in  numbers  than  it  was  a  few  years  after  it 
was  started  but  it  is  great  in  power  and  influence.  The  thou- 
sands of  dollars  of  credit  which  it  has  dispensed  during  its 
existence  stamped  out  usury  in  Loreggia  and  has  raised  many 
a  poor  man  out  of  abject  want  into,  a  state  of  competency 
where  he  could  support  his  family  in  comfort.  The  habits 
of  thrift  and  industry  which  it  inculcated  and  fostered,  and 
the  spirit  of  independence,  honor  and  fraternity  which  it 
awakened  among  its  members  by  making  them  the  responsi- 
ble managers  and  liable  one  and  aU  for  the  society's  debts, 
did  much  to  elevate  the  moral  tone  of  the  parish.  The  re- 
sults in  reforming  the  moral  and  economic  condition  of  the 
lowly  and  impoverished  classes  of  which  it  was  composed 
were  quick  to  appear.  Six  years  after  it  was  organized  the 
priest  of  the  village  said : 

They  are  going  now  less  to  the  saloons,  and  they  are  work- 
ing harder  and  longer.  Since  only  respectable  persons  are  ad- 
mitted as  members,  the  effect  has  been  that  even  drunkards 
have  resolved  no  longer  to  frequent  the  saloons  and  have  kept 
their  vow.  Ignorant  men  of  50  years  and  over  have  learned 
to  write  so  as  to  be  able  to  sign  applications  for  loans  or  notes 
or  bills.  Here  an  individual,  refused  admission  because  he  had 
applied  to  the  board  of  charity  for  help,  has  taken  the  steps 
to  have  his  name  erased  from  its  lists,  and  now  instead  of  de- 
pending on  alms,  lives  upon  his  own  work  with  the  aid  of  the 
money  suppHed  him  by  the  society.  There  a  poor  hired  hand 
who  was  barely  able  to  support  himself  has  purchased  a  cow 
and  paid  his  debts  vnth  the  proceeds  of  the  milk  and  cheese, 
and  yet  has  been  able  to  keep  the  calf,  a  thing  which  he  could 
never  have  accomplished  without  the  aid  of  the  society. 

This  shows  that  rural  cooperative  credit  started  in  Italy 
among  the  very  poorest  of  the  poor.  But  it  is  no  longer  confined 
to  its  original  humble  circumstances.     It   has   spread   over 


ITALY:  LTJZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     357 

the  entire  country  and  serves  all  sorts  and  conditions  of  farm- 
ers. There  were  in  1913  at  least  2,094  rural  credit  associa- 
tions. One-third  of  them  are  non-sectarian  and  the  rest  are 
Catholic.  The  former  are  not  consolidated  into  any  system, 
although  about  300  of  them  belong  to  the  National  Federa- 
tion of  Eural  Credit  Societies,  which  succeeded  a  similar 
organization  founded  by  WoUemborg  at  Padua  in  1887. 
This  Federation  is  not  an  auditing  or  supervising  body.  It 
has  no  control  over  its  adherents.  Its  sole  object  is  to  in- 
crease the  number  of  credit  societies,  encourage  their  devel- 
opment, and  promote  and  protect  their  interest  by  means 
adapted  to  the  occasion.  Its  official  organ  is  La  Cooperazione 
Rurale,  founded  by  WoUemborg  in  1885,  the  oldest  journal 
for  cooperative  propaganda  in  Italy. 

The  Catholic  rural  credit  societies  are  mostly  all  grouped 
in  diocesan  unions,  which  in  turn  are  united  to  the  National 
Federation  of  Catholic  Rural  Credit  Societies  organized  in 

1909,  upon  which  the  Pope  by  a  rescript  dated  January  35, 

1910,  pronounced  his  Apostolic  blessing.  A  large  number 
of  them  do  cooperative  buying  for  members,  while  there  is 
a  greater  tendency  toward  share  capital  among  the  Catho- 
lic than  among  the  non-sectarian  credit  societies.  Otherwise, 
there  is  little  to  distinguish  the  two  except  that  all  members 
and  officers  of  the  Catholic  societies  must  be  of  that  faith. 

The  position  of  the  Church  in  regard  to  this  matter  for 
Italy  as  weU  as  for  foreign  lands  is  defined  in  the  epistles 
of  Cardinal  Merry  del  Val  to  Bishop  Bougouin  of  Perigueux 
and  Sarlat  on  July  29,  1912,  to  Count  Stanislaus  Medolago 
Albioi  on  March  15,  1910,  and  to  Louis  Durand  on  April  17, 
1910.  All  these  are  repetitions  of  the  injunctions  laid  down 
in  the  encyclicals  Berum  Novarum  and  Longinque  Oceani. 
In  the  former,  issued  May  15, 1891,  Pope  Leo  XIII  declared : 
"Christian  workmen  must  do  one  of  two  things,  either  join-- 
associations  in  which  their  religion  will  be  exposed  to  peril, 
or  form  associations  among  themselves — ^unite  their  forces 
and  shake  off  courageously  the  yoke  of  so  unrighteous  and 
intolerable  an  oppression.  No  man  who  does  not  wish  to 
expose  man's  chief  good  to  extreme  risk  will  for  a  moment 


358  EUEAL    CREDITS 

hesitate  to  say  "that  the  second  alternative  should  by  all  means 
he  adopted."  In  the  latter,  issued  on  January  6,  1895,  for 
Catholics  in  the  United  States,  he  declared:  "Now  as  re- 
gards entering  societies  ....  Catholics  ought  to  prefer  to 
associate  with  Catholics,  a  course  which  will  be  very  condu- 
cive to  the  safeguarding  of  their  faith."  Further  on,  in  re- 
ferriag  to  working  classes  of  all  kinds,  he  said  that  they 
"surely  have  the  right  to  unite  in  associations  for  the  promo- 
tion of  their  interests,  a  right  acknowledged  by  the  Church 
and  unopposed  by  nature."  The  deep  interest  displayed  by 
the  Church  has  given  a  strong  impetus  to  the  movement  for 
creating  Catholic  rural  credit  societies,  which  began  in  1890 
after  Wollemborg  had  established  44  societies. 

Statistics  regarding  the  rural  credit  societies  of  Italy 
are  meager,  for  the  reason  that  there  are  no  federations  or 
supervising  authorities  to  which  they  are  all  required  to 
report.  The  work  of  gathering  the  figures  is  voluntary  and 
it  is  not  completely  done  nor  kept  up  to  date.  Some  of  the 
societies  have  capital  formed  by  shares,  but  most  of  them 
do  not  require  their  members  to  subscribe  to  shares  and  they 
exact  only  a  small  fee  of  a  few  lire  upon  admission.  The 
societies  depend  mainly  upon  money  borrowed  from 
larger  banks  and  upon  deposits  for  carrying  on  their  opera- 
tions. In  1913  their  capital  and  reserves -totaled  $600,000. 
The  deposits  amounted  to  about  $20,000,000,  most  of  which 
came  from  outsiders.  The  interest  rate  varies  from  3.5  to 
4  per  cent.  They  do  a  considerable  business  in  the  acceptance 
of  bills,  and  grant  both  short-  and  long-time  loans.  Short- 
time  loans  are  those  which  run  for  two  years  or  under.  They 
are  made  upon  three-months'  bills,  renewed  from  time  to  time 
with  interest  paid  in  advance.  Long-time  loans  run  from  two 
to  ten  years,  and  are  repayable  by  instalments  or  annuities. 
The  total  amount  of  loans  passed  in  1913  was  about  $50,000,- 
000.  The  interest  rate  on  the  credit  accorded  never  runs  more 
than  a  point  or  two  over  that  of  the  deposits,  since  in  all 
societies  the  services  of  the  officers  are  gratuitous  and  the 
managerial  expenses  slight. 

The  rural  credit  societies  are  very  unequally  distributed 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     359 

geographically.  One-half  of  them  are  in  northern  Italy.  In 
the  center  there  are  only  ahout  240,  in  the  south  190,  and  on 
the  islands  436.  One  bank  has  over  800  members,  a  few  have 
100  or  more,  but  the  average  membership  is  between  40  and 
60.  Assimiiag  for  each  bank  100,  the  total  number  of  mem- 
bers would  be  209,400,  a  goodly  army,  but  only  a  small  por- 
tion of  the  more  than  9,000,000  farmers  of  Italy. 

The  number  of  rural  credit  societies  is  largest  where 
the  population  is  most  enlightened  and  thrifty.  The  back- 
wardness of  agriculture  in  central,  southern  and  insular,  as 
compared  with  northern,  Italy,  is  a  subject  in  which  the 
Government  has  long  manifested  deep  concern.  In  applying 
the  remedies  devised,  state  aid  has  been  resorted  to  in  order 
to  stimulate  private  initiative,  and  as  a  result  there  is  much 
state-aided  cooperation  in  those  regions.  The  Italian  consti- 
tution allows  special  laws  to  be  enacted  for  any  person  or 
class  or  for  any  part  of  the  country,  and  Parliament  began 
to  exercise  this  right  at  an  early  date  in  behalf  of  agricul- 
ture. 

The  first  legislation  strove  to  adapt  existing  institutions 
to  the  needs  of  farmers  and  to  give  them  greater  commercial 
credit  facilities,  but  the  Government  eventually  became  imbued 
with  the  spirit  of  the  cooperative  movement  and  now  all  its 
projects  are  based  on  the  encouragement  of  cooperation. 
Eight  central  institutions  or  systems  have  been  created  by 
special  laws  for  the  central  and  southern  mainland  and  for 
the  islands.  The  outstanding  credit  accorded  by  these  con- 
cerns to  farmers  amounted  in  1912  to  $7,200,000,  most  of 
which  was  distributed  through  local  cooperative  associations, 
in  accordance  with  the  preference  expressed  by  the  laws.  It 
is  necessary  to  cite  only  the  more  important  of  these  laws. 
In  1901  the  Bank  of  Naples  was  instructed  to  apply  up  to 
one-fifth  of  its  savings  deposits  in  short-term  personal  loans 
to  farmers  in  its  province  and  in  Sardinia,  preferably 
through  associations  of  a  cooperative  character.  In  1902 
the  Agrarian  Credit  Institute  of  Latium  was  created  for  the 
province  of  Eome.  The  Government  obliged  the  savings 
banks  of  Milan  and  Rome  to  make  it  donations  of  300,000 


360  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

and  200,000  lire,  respectively,  and  the  Bank  of  Italy  to  ad- 
vance to  it  500,000  lire.  Thus  it  started  -with  a  working 
capital  of  1,000,000  lire  or  about  $200,000.  The  Institute  can 
transact  business  only  through  cooperative  associations,  with 
the  exception  that  it  may  deal  directly  with  the  farmers  in 
places  where  no  such  associations  exist.  Loans  must  be  re-, 
paid  within  one  year  unless  they  are  granted  for  the  purchase 
of  livestock  or  machinery,  in  which  case  they  may  run  for 
three  years.  The  credit  is  usually  accorded  by  discounting 
bills  passed  through  the  rural  banks  or  cooperative  associa- 
tions. The  central  and  intermediary  institution  may  each 
charge  one  per  cent.  The  rate  to  the  individual  farmer  never 
exceeds  by  two  per  cent  the  rate  of  the  Bank  of  Italy.  A 
certain  percentage  of  the  annual  profits  is  given  by  way  of 
interest  or  dividends  to  the  banks  which  supplied  the  Insti- 
tute with  its  capital,  and  the  rest  is  set  aside  for  the  reserves. 
Attached  to  the  Institute  ia  1911  were  109  associations  with 
over  20,000  members,  and  it  furnishes  a  large  portion  of 
the  money  which  is  used  in  the  province  for  agriculture.  The 
amount  of  loans  which  any  association  is  permitted  to  have 
outstanding  with  it  is  limited  to  $4,000. 

In  1904  the  Provincial  Bank  for  the  BasUicata,  with 
headquarters  at  Potenza,  was  created  with  a  fund  of  $400,- 
000  advanced  by  the  state  for  60  years,  free  of  interest  during 
the  first  decade  and  after  that  bearing  interest  at  two  per  cent 
for  the  next  .five  years.  In  addition,  it  was  given  all  the 
unwooded  lands  belonging  to  the  state  and  all  the  lands 
which  it  might  reclaim  along  the  rivers  in  the  province.  This 
bank  may  extend  both  short-  and  long-time  credit,  either 
directly  to  the  farmers  or  through  the  agricultural  consor- 
tiums, monti  frumentarii  (public  granaries),  rural  banks, 
and  cooperative  associations.  Interest  on  short-term  loans 
must  not  exceed  four  per  cent,  and  on  long-time  loans,  2.5 
per  cent.  The  latter  are  given  for  acquiring  or  improving 
small  homesteads,  and  cannot  run  for  over  50  years. 

In  1906  the  Victor  Emanuel  Bank  was  created  for  Co- 
senza,  Catanzaro  and  Eeggio.  It  was  endowed  by  the  state 
with  about  $400,000,  or  one-half  of  the  taxes  on  the  lands 


ITALY:  LFZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     361 

in  those  provinces  during  a  certain  length  of  time.  It  may 
grant  both  long-  and  short-time  credit,  but  its  principal  ob- 
ject is  to  make  cash  loans  to  the  farmers  through  the  usual 
intermediaries.  The  interest  rate  cannot  exceed  five  per  cent. 
In  the  same  year  an  agricultural  department  was  established 
in  the  Bank  of  Sicily  for  making  short-term  loans,  preferably 
through  cooperative  societies,  and  $600,000  of  its  own  funds 
and  $400,000  from  the  Bank  of  Palermo  were  set  aside  for 
this  purpose. 

In  1906  also  the  Government  created  a  provincial  agri- 
cultural credit  bank  in  each  of  the  Neapolitan,  Sicilian  and 
Sardinian  land  register  districts,  with  the  exception  of  the 
provinces  of  Potenza  and  Naples.  These  banks,  which  num- 
ber 18,  were  endowed  by  the  state  with  $3,765,353.  The 
savings  banks  of  the  provinces  were  compelled  to  advance 
this  money,  successively  in  proportion  to  needs,  in  the  form 
of  loans,  now  reduced  to  35  years  at  3.5  per  cent.  The  sav- 
ings banks  are  being  repaid  out  of  the  land  tax,  a  certain 
portion  of  which  was  set  aside  for  this  purpose.  The  objects 
of  these  provincial  agricxdtural  banks  are  to  make  short-term 
loans  for  distinctively  agricultural  purposes.  In  1911  they 
were  placed  under  the  management  of  the  savings-bank  de- 
partment of  the  Bank  of  Naples  and  the  agricidtural  depart- 
ment of  the  Bank  of  Sicily.  The  latter  bank  was  empowered 
to  use  one-fourth  of  the  endowment  of  the  agricultural  banks 
entrusted  to  its  care  in  loans  to  cooperative  societies.  Fur- 
thermore, it  may  use  one-tenth  of  the  net  profits  of  each 
bank  in  giving  prizes  to  encourage  agriculture.  Two  experi- 
enced farmers  must  be  made  members  of  the  discount  com- 
mittees of  all  branches  of  the  Banks  of  Naples  and  Sicily 
which  do  business  with  the  agricultural  banks.  This  system 
is  imder  the  supervision  of  the  Ministers  of  Agriculture  and 
Finance. 

In  1907  the  two  Casse  AdempriviH  of  Sardinia  were  con- 
verted into  provincial  agricultural  credit  banks  for  that 
island,  and  granted  a  loan  from  the  state  of  $600,000  for  50 
years  at  two  per  cent  interest  beginning  in  the  tenth  year. 
They  were  given  also  a  sum  equal  to  one-half  of  the  tax  on 


362  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

land  as  registered  in  1905  in  their  districts;  and  they  were 
authorized  and  instructed  to  make  with  these  funds  and 
their  own  capital,  short-  and  long-term  loans  to  farmers 
through  cooperative  hanks  and  the  other  intermediaries  men- 
tioned above.  The  rate  of  interest  for  short-term  loans  is 
limited  to  four  per  cent,  and  for  long-term  to  2.5  per  cent. 

"Ademprivili"  comes  from  the  word  "ademprivo,"  which 
is  the  Sardinian  name  for  a  form  of  servitude,  formerly  exist- 
ing on  certain  lands  irrespective  of  ownership.  The  servitude 
consisted  of  certain  rights  of  use,  such  as  the  right  to  cut 
wood  in  forested  land,  to  pasture  cattle  or  sheep  on  cleared 
lands,  to  sow  grain  in  rotation  with  pasture,  etc.  The  lands 
burdened  with  this  servitude  were  known  as  'T)eni  adempri- 
vili." From  this  is  derived  the  name  of  "Cassa  ademprivile," 
given  to  a  bank  which  advances  money  to  the  lessees  of  adem- 
privili lands  and  to  cooperative  societies  for  the  purpose  of 
buying  cattle,  agricultural  implements,  fertilizer,  and  other 
necessities  for  the  improvement  of  agricultural  properties. 
The  Cassa  Ademprivile  of  Sardinia  has  two  autonomous  sec- 
tions or  Casse,  one  at  Cagliari  and  the  other  at  Sassari,  which 
are  the  chief  towns  of  the  provinces  of  the  same  name.  The 
Cassa  makes  advances  either  in  money  or  merchandise  to  the 
"monti  frumentarii"  and  "numarii"  in  amounts  not  exceeding 
$1,930  each;  to  the  Casse  Agraria,  or  local  agricultural  banks, 
for  amounts  not  larger  than  their  capital;  and  to  the  Con- 
sorzi  Agrarii,  or  cooperative  rural  societies,  for  amounts  de- 
termined in  each  case  by  the  directors  of  the  Cassa  Adem- 
privile. In  1913  the  advances  made  by  the  Cassa  for  agricul- 
ture through  its  section  at  Cagliari  amounted  to  $398,933, 
and  through  its  section  ait  Sassari  to  $268,793. 

In  1910  an  agricultural  credit  institution  was  created 
for  the  Marches  of  Umbria,  with  a  fund  of  $140,000  of  which 
the  state  contributed  $40,000  and  the  savings  banks  of  Milan 
and  Bologna  the  rest.  In  1912  an  agrarian  credit  institute 
similar  to  the  one  in  the  province  of  Eome  was  founded  in 
Liguria  with  $100,000  donated  by  the  state.  Other  funds 
will  be  supplied  it  by  the  savings  banks  within  its  territory. 
There  is  now  on  foot  a  project  for  establishing  a  national 


ITALY:  LUZZATTI  AND  WOLLEMBOEG     363 

bank  for  cooperation  and  labor  to  operate  imder  the  auspices 
and  with  the  assistance  of  the  state.  The  project  has  been 
approved  by  the  present  administration. 

None  of  these  various  central  banks  -which  the  Govern- 
ment has  set  up  for  central,  southern  and  insular  Italy  is 
allowed  to  do  business  with  the  farmers  directly  if  there  are 
any  rural  banks,  consortiums,  or  agricultural  bodies  either 
of  an  incorporated  or  cooperative  form  to  serve  as  intermedi- 
aries, and  all  are  expected  to  encourage  the  formation  of 
such  intermediaries,  particularly  of  the  cooperative  kind, 
while  they  have  the  right  to  inspect  and  supervise  the  reor- 
ganization, if  necessary,  of  those  with  which  they  have  deal- 
ings. These  central  banks  are,  in  fact,  the  official  organs 
of  the  Government  for  introducing  cooperative  credit  among 
poor  or  ignorant  farmers  who  lack  the  standing  and  initia- 
tive to  help  themselves.  Several  of  them  were  called  into 
existence  and  endowed  with  public  funds  in  consequence  of 
earthquakes,  pests  and  plagues  which  devastated  wide  areas, 
and  they  assisted,  it  is  true,  all  who  applied  until  normal 
conditions  were  restored.  But  usually  they  give  preference 
to  the  smallest  loans  offering  the  highest  security.  The 
Banks  of  Naples  and  Sicily  are  allowed  considerable  discre- 
tion, but  strict  rules  for  according  credit  have  been  laid  down 
for  the  rest.  In  Liguria,  for  instance,  the  maximum  loan  is 
$600  for  three  years.  The  money  may  be  used  only  for  the 
purchase  of  livestock,  implements  or  machinery.  Loans  of 
$200  may  be  granted  for  two  years  for  the  purchase  of  fer- 
tilizer or  for  the  necessaries  for  planting  biennial  crops. 
Loans  for  the  same  amount  may  be  granted  for  only  one 
year  for  other  purposes  of  cultivation  and  harvesting.  It 
will  be  seen  that  these  state-aided  banks  of  Italy  are  not 
for  large  or  well-to-do  farmers. 


CHAPTEE  XXVI 

THE    DUAL    MONAECHY 

Conditions  in  Austria. — ^Barly  Cooperative  Movements. — Sehulze-De- 
litzseh  Banks  and  EaifEeisen  Credit  Societies  in  Austria. — Ger- 
man Federation  of  Austrian  Agricultural  Cooperative  So- 
cieties.— State  and  Provincial  Aid. — Conditions  in  Hungary. — 
Early  Cooperative  Movement  and  Count  Karolyi. — Hungarian 
Central  Society  for  Cooperative  Credit,  the  Centre. — Organiza- 
tion, Duties  and  Privileges. — Success  and  Failures  of  Hungarian 
Credit  System. — Three  Types  of  Cooperative  Organization  Inde- 
pendent of  the  Centre. 

AusTEiA-HuNGAET  is  divided  into  18  provinces  called 
"crown  lands,"  14  of  wMch  lie  in  Austria  and  four  in  Hun- 
gary. Some  of  them  are  coterminous  with  the  ancient  king- 
doms, duchies  and  principalities  out  of  which  they  were  cre- 
ated and  are  autonomous  in  regard  to  their  internal  affairs. 

In  Austria  at  least  eight  different  languages  are  spoken, 
but  the  Slavonic  races  comprise  about  one-half  and  the  Ger- 
man race  about  one-fourth  of  the  28,000,000  inhabitants. 
The  latter  is  most  numerous  in  Upper  and  Lower  Austria, 
Salzburg,  Styria,  Carinthia,  and  the  northern  part  of  the 
Tyrol.  Austria  is  distinctively  agricultural  and  over  one- 
third  of  its  population  are  farmers;  consequently  the  agra- 
rian element  is  strong  in  politics  but  not  always  harmonious 
because  of  this  racial  diversity.  Its  particidar  industry  is 
territorially  unequally  developed.  In  some  regions  covered 
entirely  by  large  estates  of  25,000  to  40,000  acres  agriculture 
has  not  attained  to  modem  standards,  while  in  others  where 
the  land  is  broken  up  into  very  small  holdings  it  has  almost 
reached  perfection.  All  this  explains  the  irregular  grouping 
of  agricultural  associations  according  to  nationalities  instead 
of  along  geographical  lines,  and  also  why  the  Government, 

364 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHY  365 

yielding  to  the  preponderating  influence  of  the  farmers,  has 
done  so  much  for  agriculture. 

The  farming  classes  until  1848  were  serfs  bound  to  the 
soil.  Their  emancipation  in  that  year  did  very  little  good, 
because  they  emerged  from  servitude  in  poverty  and  ignor- 
ance and  were  utterly  unable  to  adjust  themselves  to  the 
rapid  and  enormous  development  of  commerce  and  industry 
in  the  latter  half  of  the  last  century.  Besides  there  came 
the  competition  with  producers  of  cereals  and  raw  materials 
in  America  which  helped  to  bring  on  the  universal  agricul- 
tural crisis  in  Europe,  and  the  Austrian  farmers,  at  the  time 
ignored  by  the  public  authorities  and  not  yet  united,  either 
migrated  to  the  cities  in  large  numbers,  or  else  remaining  on 
their  farms,  eked  out  a  miserable  existence  between  the  ra- 
pacity of  usurers  and  the  cruelty  of  indifferent  landlords. 
Their  condition  in  most  localities  was  deplorable  even  up  to 
30  years  ago. 

Cooperation  is  claimed  to  be  of  ancient  origin  in  Austria. 
Cooperative  dairies  of  a  rudimentary  sort  have  been  traced 
back  as  far  as  the  last  centuries  of  the  Middle  Ages.  The 
present  cooperative  movement,  however,  did  not  begin  until 
around  1850.  It  made  its  appearance  in  the  form  of  mutual 
aid  societies  and  later  in  the  form  of  societies  for  collective 
purchase  of  a  peculiar  kind  afterwards  reconstructed  on 
English  principles.  Associations  for  credit  were  created  at 
Klagenfurt  in  1851,  at  Aussig  and  SchoeUnde  in  1853,  and 
at  Vienna  in  1855.  But  these  were  mixed  societies  in  which 
benevolence  was  a  prominent  feature.  Cooperative  credit  of 
the  pure  type  was  not  introduced  until  a  considerable  time 
after  its  marvelous  effectiveness  had  been  proved  iu  Germany, 
although  Austria  belonged  to  the  German  Confederation  vp 
to  1866  and  lay  near  to  the  kingdom  of  Prussia  where 
Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Eaiffeisen  were  doing  their  work. 

The  first  Schulze-Delitzsch  bank  was  opened  in  Austria 
in  1858.  At  the  end  of  12  years  there  were  943  of  these  in- 
stitutions, most  of  them  exact  copies  of  the  original.  In 
1913  there  were  3,599,  of  which  603  had  unlimited  liability. 
The   majority   of   the    Schulze-Delitzseh  banks  are  in  the 


366  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

northern  provinces  of  Bohemia,  Galicia  and  Moravia.  They 
are  grouped  by  region  or  nationality  into  federations  which 
embrace  societies  for  all  cooperative  purposes.  The  first  so- 
cieties formed  joined  the  German  union  which  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  established  at  Weimar,  but  they  dissolved  this  alli- 
ance iu  1872,  and  under  their  leader  Ziller  founded  the 
Federation  of  Schulze-Delitzsch  Societies  of  Austria.  This 
Austrian  Federation  is  modeled  precisely  after  its  German 
prototype.  It  has  seven  unions,  four  of  whieh  consist  entirely 
of  credit  societies,  but  although  national  ia  its  scope  it  has 
not  brought  into  its  fold  much  more  than  one-fifth  of  the 
credit  societies  in  existence. 

About  500  of  the  Austrian  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  are 
exclusively  agricultural  and  many  of  the  rest  have  farmers 
among  their  members.  No  statistics  have  been  compiled 
showing  the  exact  amount  of  agricultural  business  done  but 
the  figures  must  be  large.  Nevertheless,  all  these  banks  oper- 
ate along  urban  lines,  having  shares  of  a  size  even  greater 
than  that  of  their  German  prototypes  and  extending  credit 
mainly  by  accepting  and  discounting  bills  running  for  three 
months  or  less. 

The  first  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies  in  Austria  were 
founded  in  1886.  The  date,  however,  is  disputed.  A  GaUi- 
cian  report  to  the  convention  of  the  International  Coopera- 
tive Alliance  fixes  the  year  as  1880,  and  Louis  Durand  at 

1887,  while  others  assert  that  a  society  of  this  type  was 
started  in  Moravia  in  the  early  sixties.  Be  that  as  it  may, 
there  were  two  known  societies  at  the  end  of  1886,  31  in 

1888,  and  182  in  1890,  and  then  they  began  to  increase  by 
leaps  and  bounds.  Five  years  later  there  were  1,028,  while 
the  official  statistics  for  1912  show  7,991,  with  a  membership 
exceeding  one  million.  In  1910  their  business,  credits  and 
debits  exceeded  $216,000,000,  and  the  interest  rate  on  de- 
posits ran  from  three  to  4.5  per  cent,  and  on  loans  from  four 
to  six  per  cent.  The  cost  of  management  is  so  slight  that  it 
does  not  average  over  85  cents  per  member  a  year. 

The  Austrian  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies  are  nearly  all 
rural,  although  they  have  many  industrials,  shopkeepers  and 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHY  367 

small  merchants  among  their  members.  The  number  of 
members  per  bank  rarely  exceeds  150  and  is  often  as  low  as 
20.  The  deposits,  taken  from  anybody,  are  so  abundant  that 
in  nearly  every  place  the  banks. obtain  from  this  source  all 
the  money  they  need  for  carrying  on  their  operations;  in 
fact,  the  amount  of  the  deposits  in  1910  exceeded  the  amount 
of  the  outstanding  loans.  This  indicates  that  while  the  farm- 
ers are  willing  to  trust  the  societies  with  their  savings,  many 
are  still  unaccustomed  to  banking  usages,  and  when  they 
want  credit,  they  prefer  to  go  secretly  to  their  friends  or 
the  money  lenders  rather  than  let  their  neighbors  know  that 
they  are  in  need  of  assistance.  Hence  for  lack  of  other  busi- 
ness these  rural  credit  societies  have  been  compelled  to  invest 
much  of  their  funds  in  real-estate  mortgages,  in  spite  of  the 
fact  that  it  is  contrary  to  their  principles  to  do  so.  In 
Galicia,  for  instance,  over  one-half  of  the  credit  accorded  is 
for  acquiring  land,  erecting  buildings  and  improving  the 
soil.  Such  loans  run  from  ten  years  and  are  made  repayable 
by  instalments.  The  short-term  loans  run  up  to  two  years 
and  the  security  exacted  is  usually  the  signatures  of  two  in- 
dorsers  on  the  note  of  the  borrowing  member. 

The  Austrian  differ  from  the  Grerman  Eaiffeisen  credit 
societies  in  that  the  former  charge  entrance  fees,  of  ten 
crowns  ($2.45)  or  imder,  and  in  some  cases  distribute  divi- 
dends. As  a  rule,  however,  any  profits  not  needed  for  the 
reserves  are  devoted  to  some  object  of  public  utility  connected 
with  agriculture.  They  do  not  teach  Christianily,  although 
each  society  is  generally  composed  of  persons  of  the  same 
faith  or  race.  Moreover,  collective  purchase  is  not  always 
a  part  of  their  business  as  it  is  in  Germany.  But  they  have 
displayed  the  German  aptitude  to  combine  and  create  a 
system. 

The  agricultural  cooperative  associations  of  Austria  have 
formed  central  banks  and  racial  or  provincial  federations, 
and  nearly  all  belong  to  the  German  Federation  of  Austrian 
Agricultural  Cooperative  Societies.  This  body,  formed  in 
1897  with  headquarters  at  Vienna,  is  similar  to  the  German 
Imperial  Federation.    Twenty-eight  of  the  34  provincial  fed- 


368  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

erations  and  many  of  the  18  central  banks  belong  to  it,  and 
it  thus  embraces  almost  60  per  cent  of  the  rural  credit  so- 
cieties, irrespective  of  faith,  race  or  language.  In  1911  the 
most  important  German  federations  and  central  banks 
founded  a  general  agricultural  bank  with  a  capital  fixed  at 
$800,000,  with  the  right  to  raise  it  to  double  that  amount. 

Thus  in  Austria  there  is  a  great  and  continually  spread- 
ing network  of  little  societies  encouraging  thrift  and  helping 
agriculture  by  gathering  up  the  savings  in  the  rural  districts 
and  lending  them  out  to  the  farmers  who  have  need  of  credit. 
In  1910  there  was  one  rural  credit  society  for  every  3,647 
of  the  population,  excluding  Vienna,  and  the  ratio  may 
be  somewhat  better  today.  But  although  this  splendid  and 
now  indispensable  system  of  rural  credit  facilities  is  self- 
supporting  and  self-governing,  it  did  not  spring  entirely 
from  private  initiative.  Its  development  is  due  in  a  large 
measure  to  direct  oflScial  activity  of  the  Grovernment.  "No 
other  country,"  writes  Dr.  Ertl,  bureau  chief  in  the  Austrian 
Ministry  of  Agriculture,  rather  extravagantly,  "has  looked 
upon  the  encouragement  of  cooperation  as  such  a  necessity 
for  agriculture.  Austria  must  be  considered  as  the  most 
notable  champion  of  state  aid." 

The  Austrian  Government  began  its  activities  in  behalf 
of  agricultural  cooperation  by  making  small  donations  to 
the  rural  banks  in  Istria  and  Dalmatia.  It  gave  them  also 
the  privilege  of  borrowing  at  the  public  savings  banks.  Later 
on  it  ordered  officeholders  from  the  highest  functionaries 
down  to  the  village  schoolmasters  to  interest  themselves  not 
only  as  campaigners  but  even  as  organizers  of  these  little  in- 
stitutions, and  supplied  them  with  tracts  and  literature  for 
expanding  the  cooperative  idea  throughout  the  land.  At  the 
first  Austrian  Eaiffeisenist  Congress  in  1897  the  Government 
took  a  leading  part  in  bringing  about  the  formation  of  the 
Federation,  and  in  the  following  year  made  it  a  grant  of 
$1,960,  which  was  afterward  increased  to  $5,880.  Since 
1901  the  Government  has  had  a  representative  on  the  board 
of  directors  of  the  Federation  and  a  bureau  for  credit  so- 
cieties in  the  Department  of  Agriculture. 


THE   DUAL  MONAECHY  369i 

Some  of  the  provinces  took  steps  at  an  early  date  to  for- 
ward the  cooperative  movement  and  have  been  more  gener- 
ous than  the  national  Government  in  giving  actual  financial 
assistance.  A  few  instances  may  be  cited  as  typical  of  all. 
The  Diet  of  Lower  Austria  made  an  outright  gift  of  $50,- 
000  and  an  advance  of  $500,000  to  the  central  bank  in  the 
province.  In  1903  it  paid  $1,350  to  the  local  banks,  besides 
$5,455  for  expenses  of  the  auditors,  and  in  addition  a  fund 
of  over  $50,000  was  deposited  with  the  central  bank  for 
lending  out  to  the  local  banks  at  two  per  cent  a  year.  In 
1888  this  province  began  to  grant  sums  of  $100,  $80  and  then 
$60  to  new  local  banks  to  meet  the  first  costs  of  organiza- 
tion. 

Upper  Austria  compelled  the  Landesausschuss  to  lend  at 
least  $40,000  a  year  to  the  rural  credit  societies  at  three  per 
cent  per  annum  and  $40  without  interest  to  each  new  society 
formed.  About  the  same  time  Bohemia,  Bukowina  and  Ca- 
rinthia  adopted  the  practice  of  making  advances  to  the  rural 
credit  societies  and  other  cooperative  associations,  for  meet- 
ing the  first  costs  of  organization,  supporting  their  unions, 
conducting  inspections  and  diffusing  information.  Galieia 
in  1899  placed  $400,000  at  the  disposal  of  the  rural  credit 
societies,  in  addition  to  loans  previously  made.  It  also 
assumed  the  cost  of  creating  a  central  agency  for  the  banks 
and  a  part  of  the  expense  of  forming  new  societies,  to  say 
nothing  of  the  money  spent  in  propaganda.  In  Istria,  Mo- 
ravia, Silesia,  Salzbourg,  Styria,  the  Tyrol  and  Yoralberg, 
money  was  appropriated  soon  after  the  movement  began,  for 
making  loans  without  interest  to  the  local  societies  and  for 
giving  them  the  necessary  inspection,  instruction  and  in- 
formation. 

The  course  of  intervention  which  gave  impetus  to  the 
agricultural  cooperative  movement  in  the  beginning  in  Aus- 
tria has  been  continued  down  to  the  present  time  by  the 
national  and  provincial  governments.  Although  the  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  banks  have  persistently  refused  all  state  aid,  the 
rural  societies  have  always  been  willing  recipients  of  it. 
Today  the  latter  enjoy  exemptions  or  reductions  in  respect 


370  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

to  certain  taxes.  They  are  allowed  the  free  use  of  the  mails 
in  their  correspondence  with  the  Government.  They  are  us- 
ing about  $300,000  advanced  by  the  national  Government 
and  other  large  amounts  from  the  provincial  governments. 
Each  new  credit  society  that  is  formed  may  receive  a  $60 
loan,  while  all  are  benefited  directly  or  indirectly  by  the 
appropriations  made  from  the  public  funds  for  propaganda 
and  administrative  purposes,  for  carrying  on  inspection  and 
investigations,  for  giving  instruction  to  cooperative  officers, 
and  for  disseminating  information  for  stimulating  coopera- 
tion. If  a  bill  for  the  establishment  of  a  national  bank  for 
cooperative  societies  which  is  now  before  the  Diet  is  passed, 
they  will  also  obtain  their  proportionate  share  in  the  advan- 
tages to  be  derived  from  the  $1,200,000  with  which  the  Gov- 
ernment proposes  to  subsidize  it. 

The  cooperative  societies  of  all  types  in  Austria  are  regu- 
lated by  the  law  of  1873,  as  amended  by  the  law  of  1903, 
which  requires  every  society  to  submit  to  a  biennial  audit 
by  the  provincial  authority  or  by  the  Federation  if  this  duty 
is  entrusted  to  it  by  the  province.  The  law  permits  limited 
liability  and  joint  and  several  unlimited  liability.  The  ad- 
ministrative organs  of  a  society  are  similar  to  those  in  Ger- 
many, with  the  exception  that  the  board  of  supervision  is 
optional. 

In  the  space  of  36  years  3,660  Austrian  cooperative  credit 
associations  out  of  a  total  number  of  15,953  have  disappeared. 
Bankruptcy  was  the  cause  in  only  249  of  the  cases. 

The  four  provinces  or  crown  lands  of  Hungary  comprise 
the  autonomous  kingdom  of  Croatia-Slavonia,  Hungary 
proper,  the  principality  of  Transylvania,  and  the  territory 
known  as  the  Military  Frontier  on  the  Balkan  border.  There 
are  as  many  different  races  and  languages  in  Hungary  as 
in  Austria,  but  the  Magyars  predominate,  representing 
twelve  millions  of  the  20,886,787  inhabitants  (1910).  About 
70  per  cent  of  the  population  are  farmers.  Agriculture  is 
backward  although  the  soil  is  rich  and  fertile,  but  year  by 
year  it  is  being  bettered  by  means  of  cooperation. 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHY  371 

Family  cooperative  societies  have  existed  in  Croatia-Sla- 
vonia  from  time  immemorial  and  are  still  numerous,  while 
friendly  societies  appeared  in  various  parts  of  the  country 
about  the  middle  of  the  last  century.  The  first  was  the 
Savings  and  Aid  Bank  established  at  Bezstercze  in  1851,  and 
the  second  a  similar  institution  established  at  Kolozsvar  in 
1858.  In  the  sixties  seven  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  were 
formed  in  Transylvania  by  some  small  Saxon  manufacturers 
and  "annual  societies"  were  started  in  the  trans-Danubian 
districts.  The  latter  are  credit  associations  in  which  the 
shares  are  issued  in  annual  series  and  are  matured  by 
monthly  instalments  paid  for  six  years.  The  first  of  these 
was  formed  at  Gyor  in  1864,  and  the  second  at  Pecs  in  1866, 
and  later  on  others  appeared  at  Szekesfehervar,  Komarom, 
and  elsewhere.  The  society  at  Pecs  is  still  running.  Offi- 
cials in  the  Hungarian  civil  service  organized  a  union  on 
the  friendly-society  plan  in  1864,  which  was  transformed 
into  a  cooperative  society  in  1869.  The  Pesth  Savings  and 
Loan  Society  was  formed  for  this  union  eight  years  after. 
Counting  all  these  types  there  were  103  cooperative  banks 
and  credit  associations  in  1870  and  by  1885  their  number 
had  increased  to  398.  Their  combined  business  was  heavy, 
but  with  the  exception  of  the  Austrian  and  Slavonian  family 
cooperative  societies,  which  are  not  banks,  their  members 
were  industrials  and  persons  living  in  the  towns  or  cities. 

Cooperative  credit  as  an  organized  important  factor  did 
not  make  its  appearance  in  the  agricidtural  life  of  Hungary 
until  after  the  International  Agricultural  Congress  held  at 
Budapest  in  1885  under  the  presidency  of  Count  Alexander 
Karolyi.  Many  notables  attended  this  Congress,  and  Eaif- 
feisen  was  its  particular  theme.  Leone  Wollemborg  told  of 
what  was  being  done  in  Italy,  and  Endre  read  a  letter  from 
Eaiffeisen  himself  and  in  an  impassioned  address  declared 
that  the  plans  of  the  great  father  of  German  rural  coop- 
erative credit  were  the  only  way  by  which  the  Hungarian 
peasants  could  be  rescued  from  the  thraldom  of  usury  and 
the  miserable  condition  into  which  they  had  fallen. 

The  discussions  at  this  Congress  and  the  information  im- 


372  KTJEAL   CEEDITS 

parted  inspired  Dr.  Charles  Wolff,  who  a  little  while  before 
had  begun  to  study  the  subject,  to  renew  his  efforts  to  get 
the  Saxon  farmers  of  Transylvania  to  form  Eaiffeisen  soci- 
eties. But  most  important  of  all,  it  awakened  a  deep  and 
-abiding  interest  in  the  wealthy  and  powerful  Count  Karolyi, 
who  imctnediately  resolved  to  undertake  the  huge  task  of 
making  men  out  of  the  downtrodden,  apathetic  and  ignorant 
Hungarian  peasants  through  the  iastrumentality  of  coopera- 
tion. From  that  day  on  he  strove  with  all  his  energies  to 
accomplish  this  task,  and  he  was  soon  recognized  as  the 
apostle  and  foremost  leader  of  cooperation  in  his  country, 
and  justly  so,  because  it  was  through  his  influence  and  mu- 
nificence that  a  system  for  associated  action  was  established 
for  the  farmers  of  Hungary.  He  was  ably  assisted  by  Ig- 
natius Daranyi,  Minister  of  Agriculture,  and  by  Stephen 
Bemat,  the  founder  of  the  cooperative  press,  whose  brilliant 
talents  as  a  writer  did  much  to  arouse  and  direct  the  enthusi- 
asm which  brought  the  movement  to  success. 

Count  Karolyi  started  the  movement  by  inducing  the 
county  of  Pesth  Philis-Solt-Kiskun  to  found  a  County  Credit 
Association  of  the  EaifEeisen  type.  The  county  and  promi- 
nent landowners  subscribed  to  800  founders'  shares  of  $75 
each.  This  association  helped  to  form  numerous  local  credit 
societies  within  its  confines,  and  in  1894  extended  its  sphere 
so  as  to  include  contiguous  territory,  especially  in  Transyl- 
vania. It  was  succeeded  by  a  bank  with  a  national  scope 
which  it  founded  in  1896  with  aid  of  the  largest  savings 
bank  in  the  kingdom.  The  work  of  Dr.  Wolff  also  began  to 
show  results  about  this  time,  and  with  the  aid  of  a  savings 
bank  he  formed  a  regional  bank  and  a  number  of  local  credit 
associations  of  the  Eaiffeisen  type  in  the  Saxon  villages  of 
Transylvania.  Another  independent  movement  was  started 
later  on  in  the  district  between  the  Drave  and  the  Save. 

In  1898  there  were  465  credit  societies  in  Count  Karoyli's 
system  and  796  belonging  to  other  groups  or  scattered 
throughout  the  country.  Some  of  the  latter  were  coopera- 
tive only  in  form  and  had  been  organized  by  usurers  to  decoy 
the  unwary  into  their  clutches,  a  trick  always  possible  where 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHY  373 

the  laws  do  not  limit  the  rate  of  interest  to  be  charged,  or 
the  number  of  shares  any  one  member  may  hold,  or  the 
amount  of  dividends  that  may  be  distributed.  As  for  the 
rest,  they  were  practically  all  formed  by  public-spirited  men 
through  the  higher  organizations  created  for  that  purpose, 
and  were  kept  going  by  the  easy  money  supplied  by  such 
men,  by  the  savings  banks,  or  by  the  counties  in  which  they 
were  located.  The  few  that  were  formed  by  members  them- 
selves were  located  in  the  cities  or  in  the  German  settle- 
ments. 

Everywhere  else  progress  was  made  under  difficulty  and 
frequently  halted  whenever  the  leaders  relaxed  their  grip, 
because  the  peasants,  through  their  ignorance  and  their  dis- 
trust of  innovations,  were  utterly  uuable  to  appreciate  the 
work  being  done  in  their  behalf.  But  these  1,200  or  more 
spoon-fed  credit  societies  were  accomplishing  wonders  in  abol- 
ishing usury  and  in  transforming  their  members  into  useful 
citizens  by  furnishing  them  with  the  necessary  funds  for 
earning  a  decent  living.  This  proof  of  their  worth  inspired 
newspapers,  savings  banks  and  many  rich  philanthropists  to 
encourage  their  growth,  while  Count  Karolyi  by  exerting 
his  powerful  influence  finally  induced  the  royal  government 
itself  to  become  an  active  propagandist  and  financial  sup- 
porter of  cooperation  in  all  its  forms  for  the  industrial  as 
well  as  the  agricultural  classes  but  more  especially  for  the 
latter,  a  course  which  it  was  easily  prompted  to  take  because 
at  that  time  the  socialists  whom  it  wished  to  combat  were 
stirring  up  a  feeling  of  unrest  among  the  farmers.  Socialism 
invariably  vanishes  when  cooperation  appears. 

Accordingly,  in  1898,  by  virtue  of  a  law  enacted  in  that 
year,  a  state-conceived  and  state-endowed  institution,  called 
the  Hungarian  Central  Society  for  Cooperative  Credit,  was 
established  to  serve  as  a  bank  and  a  propagating  organ  for 
cooperation  for  industrial  and  agricultural  classes  alike 
throughout  the  kingdom.  All  the  cooperative  credit  societies 
affiliated  with  this  institution  are  accorded  privileges  and 
subjected  to  regulations  of  a  special  nature  which  make  them 
entirely  different  from  the  societies  formed  under  the  coop- 


374  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

erative  law  of  1875.  This  old  law,  which  allows  both  limited 
and  unlimited  liability,  was  not  disturbed,  and  cooperative  so- 
cieties may  still  operate  and  be  formed  under  it  if  they  do 
not  wish  to  avail  themselves  of  the  advantages  offered  by  the 
new  law  and  the  institution  created  by  it,  but  they  enjoy 
only  a  few  privileges. 

The  Hungarian  Central  Society  for  Cooperative  Credit 
supplanted  the  central  bank  and  took  over  all  the  local  so- 
cieties of  Count  Karolyi's  system.  It  was  modeled  after  the 
Hungarian  Land  Mortgage  Institute  and  one  of  the  argu- 
ments advanced  to  obtain  the  charter  was  that  the  latter  con- 
cern and  the  National  Small  Holdings  Land  Mortgage  Insti- 
tute had  not  been  of  much  use  in  financing  the  small  and 
medium-sized  farmers.  This  new  institution,  popularly 
known  as  the  Centre,  is  not  cooperative,  but  its  capital  stock 
is  variable  and  may  be  increased  indefinitely.  At  the  start 
it  was  $742,350,  of  which  the  King  subscribed  $12,250,  the 
state  $245,000,  and  private  individuals  and  corporations  the 
rest  in  shares  of  $245  each.  These  are  styled  founders' 
shares,  and  they  will  be  repaid  from  a  sinking  fund  being 
created  for  that  purpose  out  of  a  certain  portion  of  the  an- 
nual profits.  Every  affiliated  society  must  subscribe  for  at 
least  one  share  of  $49,  the  liability  on  which  is  thirty  times 
that  amount.    Dividends  are  limited  to  four  per  cent  a  year. 

The  president  of  the  Centre  is  appointed  by  the  King  upon 
advice  of  the  Minister  of  Finance.  One  vice-president,  two 
members  of  the  board  of  directors  and  one  member  of  the 
committee  of  supervision  are  appointed  by  the  Minister  of 
Finance,  and  the  manager  selected  by  the  directors  from 
among  themselves  is  subject  to  his  approval,  while  all  the 
affairs  of  the  Centre  are  under  his  control  and  supervision, 
carried  out  by  a  special  government  commissioner  who  has 
power  to  stop  action  on  any  resolution  of  the  board  of  direc- 
tors pending  his  decision.  The  second  vice-president  is  ap- 
pointed by  the  Minister  of  Agriculture.  The  board  of  direc- 
tors, with  the  exception  noted,  and  the  coromittee  of  super- 
vision are  selected  at  a  general  meeting  of  the  holders  of 
founders'  shares,  in  which  the  aflBliated  societies  may  not 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHT  375 

vote  directly  but  may  be  represented  in  groups  of  delegates 
in  a  way  similar  to  that  provided  for  borrowers  in  the  Land 
Mortgage  Institute. 

The  powers  and  duties  of  the  Centre  are  to  supply  bank- 
ing facilities  to  agricultural  and  industrial  cooperative  soci- 
eties for  credit;  to  assist  small  holders  in  obtaining  long- 
term  loans;  to  foimd  cooperative  societies;  to  prepare  models 
of  by-laws  and  rules  for  the  carrying  on  of  their  business, 
and  to  supervise  and  control  such  as  are  affiliated  with  it; 
and  finally  to  promote  the  intellectual,  moral  and  material 
welfare  of  workmen  and  farmers,  especially  by  encouraging 
the  practice  of  cooperation.  It  may  establish  agencies  and 
has  been  compelled  to  maintain  them  in  Croatia  and  Sla- 
vonia. 

Certain  privileges  have  been  accorded  the  Centre  to  en- 
able it  the  better  to  perform  its  duties.  It  is  exempted  from 
the  payment  of  commercial  taxes  and  certain  stamp  and 
other  duties,  and  it  has  the  free  use  of  the  public  mails.  The 
state  has  given  it  some  hundreds  of  thousands  of  dollars 
credit  at  low  interest  rates,  and  it  may  borrow  from  and  re- 
discoimt  the  paper  of  affiliated  societies  at  all  the  other  Hun- 
garian moneyed  institutions.  It  may  receive  deposits,  ordi- 
nary and  on  current  accoimts,  but  not  savings,  and  more- 
over may  issue  debentures  free  of  all  taxation  and  legally 
usable  as  investment  for  trustee  funds.  These  debentures 
are  based  on  the  notes  of  individuals,  indorsed  by  the  soci- 
eties of  which  they  are  members  and  secured  by  a  fund  equal 
to  one-tenth  of  their  face  value  and  by  a  special  guaranty 
fund  of  $735,000  contributed  by  the  state.  To  this  security 
must  be  added  the  liability  of  the  Centre  and  affiliated  so- 
cieties. 

Cooperative  credit  societies  organized  under  the  law  of 
1898  and  affiliated  with  the  Centre  must  conform  their  arti- 
cles of  agreement  or  by-laws  with  the  models  prepared  by 
that  institution.  The  liability  of  members  is  limited  to  five 
times  the  amoimt  of  the  shares  subscribed.  This  liability 
can  be  enforced  by  third  parties  only  in  bankruptcy,  but  the 
society  itself  can  levy  equal  assessments  up  to  its  full  extent 


376  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

.    ...     .v-i-z-i 

against  members  to  meet  any  losses  not  covered  by  the  re- 
serve. The  shares  cannot  be  for  over  one  hundred  crowns 
($24.50),  and  may  be  paid  up  by  monthly  instalments  rim- 
ning  for  five  years.  Dividends  in  excess  of  five  per  cent  per 
annum  are  forbidden.  Any  surplus  is  carried  over  to  the 
reserve.  At  least  ten  per  cent  of  the  profits  must  be  put  into 
the  reserve  each  year  until  it  equals  half  the  total  of  the 
share  capital.  Members  may  withdraw  on  six  months'  no- 
tice to  take  effect  at  the  end  of  the  year.  None  may  have 
more  than  one  vote  or  cast  that  vote  by  proxy. 

The  Centre  has  the  right  to  appoint  one  member  each 
on  the  executive  conomittee  and  board  of  supervision  of  an 
affiliated  society.  The  managers  may  be  allowed  ten  per  cent 
of  the  profits  but  no  other  form  of  compensation.  The  Cen- 
tre inspects  the  society  at  least  twice  a  year,  and  may  force  it 
into  bankruptcy  if  its  affairs  are  unsatisfactory.  The  costs 
of  the  inspection  are  charged  against  the  society  or  borne 
by  the  Centre.  At  present  the  Centre  assesses  the  societies 
for  this  purpose. 

A  cooperative  credit  society  cannot  extend  its  operations 
over  more  than  two  adjacent  communes,  and  it  usually  con- 
fines itself  to  one  commune.  Its  objects  are  to  receive  de- 
posits from  all  sources  and  lend  to  members  only.  In  addi- 
tion to  supplying  the  credit  needs  of  members,  many  of  the 
agricultural  credit  societies  buy  machines  for  sale  or  rent, 
keep  breeding  cattle,  or  undertake  to  sell  supplies  of  mem- 
bers or  maintain  warehouses  for  the  storage  thereof.  A  coop- 
erative credit  society  has  the  same  tax  exemptions  as  the 
Centre,  but  its  greatest  privilege  is  that  it  has  a  lien  on  all 
the  movables  of  a  borrowing  member  which  precedes  that 
of  any  other  of  his  creditors  after  he  has  been  once  admitted 
to  membership. 

When  the  capital,  reserves  and  deposits  are  not  sufficient 
for  the  needs  of  its  members,  an  aflBliated  cooperative  credit 
society  may  then  resort  to  the  Centre  for  help  and  borrow 
directly  or  discount  the  paper  of  its  members  at  that  insti- 
tution. But  the  amount  of  the  credit  obtainable  from  this 
source  is  usually  limited  to  the  face  value  of  the  shares  sub- 


THE  DUAL  MONAECHY  377 

scribed  by  members,  plus  twice  what  has  actually  been  paid 
up  thereon  and  the  total  of  the  deposits  and  sums  invested 
by  the  local  society  with  the  Centre.  The  rate  of  interest 
charged  by  the  local  must  not  exceed  that  of  the  Centre  by 
two  per  cent  except  in  extraordinary  cases.  The  Centre's  rate 
is  usually  from  one-half  of  one  per  cent  to  one  per  cent  higher 
than  that  of  the  Austro-Hungarian  Bank,  so  the  rate  to  the 
individual  member  fluctuates  between  six  and  seven  per  cent. 

The  credit  extended  by  a  local  cooperative  credit  society 
may  be  for  either  short  or  long  term.  Short-term  credits  are 
acceptances  or  discounts  of  three-months'  paper,  or  notes 
running  for  five  years  or  under.  Liberality  is  shown  in  al- 
lowing renewals  upon  condition  of  making  small  partial  pay- 
ments. But  security  is  always  required  and  the  money  bor- 
rowed must  be  used  for  some  specified  productive  or  provi- 
dent purpose.  The  articles  of  agreement  of  each  society  must 
fix  the  maximum  for  the  credit  which  may  be  accorded  to 
any  one  member.  This  rarely  goes  beyond  15  per  cent  of  the 
society's  paid-up  capital.  The  long-term  loans  may  run  from 
10  to  50  years  and  be  repaid  either  by  instalments,  amortiza- 
tion or  in  lump.  Such  loans  are  granted  only  to  small  hold- 
ers on  mortgage,  and  usually  for  the  purpose  of  lifting  a 
more  burdensome  prior  encumbrance  or  for  acquiring  or 
improving  a  homestead.  Seventy-five  per  cent  of  the  ap- 
praised value  of  the  property  is  allowed.  Such  loans  are  not 
made  with  the  society's  own  funds,  but  in  the  following 
manner:  The  loan  is  split  into  a  first  mortgage  for  50  per 
cent  of  the  value  of  the  property,  and  into  a  second  mortgage 
for  20  per  cent  of  the  value  thereof.  Both  are  assigned  to 
the  Centre,  which  reassigns  the  first  to  some  mortgage  bank, 
and  retains  the  second  to  be  used  as  security  for  its  deben- 
tures. During  recent  years  the  real-estate  loans  have  usually 
been  turned  over  to  the  National  Land  Credit  Institute  for 
Small  Holders  and  the  National  Federation  of  Land  Credit 
Institutes,  mentioned  in  a  previous  chapter. 

In  1912  the  capital  of  the  Centre  was  roughly  $1,632,900; 
its  reserves  were  $332,413,  deposits  $7,532,392,  and  deben- 
tures in  circulation  $9,138,850.    The  affiliated  societies  num- 


378  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

bered  2,412,  of  which  226  were  industrial  and  all  the  rest 
agricultural.  Their  combined  paid-up  capital  was  $41,436,- 
500,  reserves  $11,355,400,  and  deposits  $29,845,475,  and  the 
amount  of  the  credit  accorded  to  their  665,333  members,  in- 
cluding the  discounts  of  the  Centre  and  the  long-term  loans 
taken  by  the  mortgage  banks,  amounted  to  over  $75,000,000. 
These  mortgage  loans  were  for  sums  rarely  exceeding 
$1,000,  while  the  average  size  of  the  bills  accepted  or  dis- 
counted was  $75.  Bills  as  small  as  50  cents  were  discounted, 
all  of  which  shows  that  the  business  done  is  confined  to  the 
small  folk,  as  it  was  intended  that  it  should  be. 

The  success  achieved  by  this  Crown-devised  and  state- 
aided  cooperative  credit  system  of  Hungary  was  a  surprise 
even  to  those  who  conceived  it.  The  system  was  established 
purely  as  an  experiment,  but  it  now  covers  7,777,  or  over 
one-half,  of  the  parishes  of  Hungary.  It  has  stamped  out 
usury  and  revived  agriculture  within  that  area,  and  has 
given  a  strong  impetus  to  the  cooperative  movement  which 
is  now  spreading  throughout  the  land.  But  it  has  defects 
and  shortcomings  which  are  becoming  more  apparent  with 
time. 

The  intervention  of  the  state  has  deadened  the  spirit  of 
self-help.  The  arrangement  which  deprives  the  farmers  of 
direct  representation  in  the  management  of  the  Centre  and 
even  compels  them  to  accept  persons  not  of  their  own  choos- 
ing for  certain  offices  in  the  local  societies,  violates  the  im- 
portant principle  of  cooperation  and  retards  the  develop- 
ment of  individual  independence.  Great  numbers  of  the 
societies  have  been  formed  and  are  managed  by  the  priests, 
teachers,  notaries  or  large  landowners  in  the  neighborhood, 
and  the  members  have  no  mutual  feeling  for  one  another  but 
join  simply  with  the  object  of  benefiting  themselves  alone. 
The  artificiality  arising  from  this  outside  control  has  created 
distrust  of  the  system  in  banking  circles.  Coupled  with  this 
distrust  is  the  enmity  aroused  by  the  official  favoritism  dis- 
played and  the  class  legislation  enacted  for  farmers,  and  as 
a  result  the  Centre,  which  is  now  mostly  agricultural,  finds 
difficulty  in  negotiating  its  debentures  and  rediscounting  the 


THE   DUAL  MONAECHY  379 

paper  of  the  local  societies.  Indeed,  the  system  is  badly  in 
■want  of  money  for  extending  its  activities,  and  the  Minister 
of  Agriculture  recently  acknowledged  that  unless  it  can  at- 
tract more  deposits  or  establish  better  relations  with  existing 
financial  institutions,  the  state  will  have  to  be  called  upon 
for  further  assistance. 

The  law  of  1898  authorizes  other  bodies,  such  as  county 
councils,  chambers  of  commerce  and  industry,  and  public 
agricultural  corporations  and  associations,  to  form  local  credit 
societies.  But  by  common  consent  the  organization  of  coop- 
erative credit  under  this  law  has  been  left  to  the  Centre. 
There  are  in  Hungary,  however,  quite  a  number  of  coopera- 
tive credit  societies  which  are  entirely  independent  of  the 
Centre.  Most  of  them  were  formed  before  that-  institution 
came  into  existence,  and  except  for  a  few  scattered  here  and 
there,  they  belong  to  three  distinct  groups.  The  first  group 
consists  of  the  176  credit  societies  of  the  EaifEeisen  type,  six 
wine-vault  societies,  and  48  supply  societies  connected  with 
the  savings  bank  at  Nagyszeben,  Transylvania.  They  have 
18,000  members  and  a  capital  of  about  $4,000,000.  The 
second  is  the  Servian  Federation  at  Zagrab,  with  334  soci- 
eties. They  are  chiefly  engaged  in  acquiring  leaseholds  for 
allotment  among  members.  The  third  comprises  the  352 
EaifEeisen  societies  with  38,000  members  afSliated  with  the 
Croatian  Agrarian  Bank  at  Zagrab. 


CHAPTER  XXVII 

BELGIUM,     HOLLAND,    LtTXEMBUBG,   DENMABK, 
SCANDINAVIA,   AND   SWITZERLAND 

Cooperative  Credit  Early  Devised  in  Belgium. — Credit  TTnion  of 
Brussels. — Farmers  Not  Benefited. — Comptoir  Agricoles  and  the 
General  Pension  and  Savings  Bank. — The  Boerenbond. — Syndi- 
cates.— ^Village  Associations  in  Holland. — The  Catholic  Church. — 
Eindhoven  Central  Bank. — Central  Banks  at  Utrecht  and  Alk- 
maar. — High  Degree  of  Cooperation  in  Luxemburg. — State 
Banks. — Cooperation  for  Buying  and  Selling  in  Denmark. — Gov- 
ernment Encouragement  of  Eural  Credit  Societies. — Mortgage- 
bond  Companies  of  Norway. — Early  Cooperative  Associations 
for  Sweden. — ^RaiflEeisen  Societies  in  Switzerland. — Swiss  Union 
of  Kaiffeisen  Banks. — SmaU  Banks  and  Ample  Credit. — Cattle- 
purchasing  Commissions  of  Thurgau. 

PoPTTLAB  credit  with  cooperative  features  was  devised  and 
introduced  in  Belgium  before  Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Eaif- 
feisen  had  thought  of  the  idea  of  using  self-help  instead  of 
charity  as  a  means  of  rescuing  poor  people  from  their  pov- 
erty. In  1848  Prangois  Haeck  organized  the  Credit  Union 
of  Brussels,  "without  capital  stock,  shareholders,  dividends 
or  lucrative  object,"  for  the  purpose  of  discounting  the  paper 
of  commerce,  industry  and  agrictdture  and  workers  therein 
and  procuring  for  them  the  money  they  needed  up  to  the 
limit  of  their  "moral  and  material  worth."  But  this  Union 
deviated  from  its  original  spirit  and  Belgium  lost  to  Ger- 
many the  honor  of  being  the  birthplace  of  cooperative  credit 
on  the  Continent. 

The  Credit  Union  of  Brussels  is  composed  entirely  of 
borrowers  or  prospective  borrowers  each  of  whom  has  but  one 
vote.  It  is  managed  by  a  board  of  directors,  the  usual  staff 
of  officers,  a  committee  on  membership  and  a  discount  com- 
mittee.   The  social  fund  is  variable  and  illimitable,  but  must 

380 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LFXEMBUEG,  ETC.    381 

never  fall  below  $800,000.  It  is  created  by  subscriptions  of 
persons  desiring  to  obtain  credit.  The  lowest  subscription  is 
$100.  The  maximum  is  not  fixed  but  must  correspond  ex- 
actly with  the  amount  of  the  credit  granted  or  to  be  opened 
for  each  member.  Five  per  cent  of  the  subscriptions  must 
be  paid  in  cash  and  the  rest  is  subject  to  call.  When  the 
losses  of  the  Union  exhaust  the  reserves  and  one-fourth  of 
the  paid-in  share  capital,  each  member  must  pay  his  pro- 
portionate assessment  to  the  Union.  Beyond  this  there  is 
no  liability.  The  admission  of  a  person  to  membership  estab- 
lishes his  right  and  the  extent  thereof  to  credit,  but  he  is 
required  to  furnish  adequate  security,  real  or  personal.  A 
member  may  hold  more  than  one  share,  within  limit  as  to 
number  and  value  determiaed  by  the  board  of  directors. 
This  limit  extends  in  some  cases  to  thousands  of  dollars. 

The  principal  operations  of  the  Credit  Union  of  Brussels 
are  discounts  and  rediscounts,  the  purchase  of  commercial 
paper,  the  receiving  of  deposits  and  accounts  current,  execut- 
ing orders  for  the  purchase  or  sale  of  investment  securities, 
and  making  loans  on  collateral.  All  these  operations  except 
discoimting  may  be  carried  on  with  outsiders.  Deposits  may 
be  invested  only  in  paper  maturing  in  100  days.  The  Union 
may  issue  bonds  with  fixed  time  for  payment,  but  the  amount 
in  circulation  must  not  exceed  one-tenth  of  its  share  capital. 
The  notes  or  bills  presented  by  members  for  discount  must 
not  be  longer  than  three  months.  Loans  on  collateral  may 
nm  for  100  days.  The  interest  rate  follows  that  of  the 
National  Bank,  increased  usually  by  one-fourth.  This  extra 
interest  may  be  distributed  among  the  members  as  a  rebate. 
Long-term  loans  were  granted  by  means  of  repeated  renewals 
of  notes  down  to  the  year  1877,  but  the  practice  is  not  now 
allowed.  The  profits  of  the  Credit  Union  of  Brussels  are 
disposed  of  thus:  first,  an  amount  determined  by  the  man- 
agement is  put  into  the  reserve  which  must  always  be  main- 
tained at  a  minimum  of  $5,000,  and  then  a  five  per  cent  divi- 
dend may  be  distributed;  of  the  balance  20  per  cent  is  paid 
to  employees,  five  per  cent  to  a  sanatorium,  and  75  per  cent 
goes  either  into  the  reserve  or  as  an  extra  dividend.    In  1910 


382  EUEAL    CREDITS 

the  Unioii  had  5,232  members  and  a  capital  of  $14,207,600. 
Its  discoimts  and  rediscounts  amounted  to  $50,923,600,  its 
loans  to  $5,258,400,  and  its  deposits  and  accounts  current  to 
$5,270,400.  A  five  per  cent  dividend  was  declared  in  that 
year. 

There  are  now  six  credit  unions  in  Belgium  and  a  num- 
ber in  France  and  Switzerland,  but  none  is  important  except 
the  one  at  Brussels,  while  all  have  ignored  the  farmers  and 
even  the  small  people  in  the  cities.  Their  business  comes 
mainly  from  the  better  class  of  traders  and  merchants.  The 
exclusion  of  the  farmers  is  due  to  the  fact  that  no  long-time 
loans  are  grafted.  The  exclusion  of  small  folk  results  from 
placing  no  limit  on  the  size  of  the  shares  or  the  amount  of 
dividends  which  may  be  declared.  Nevertheless  the  plan  of 
organization  and  operation  of  the  credit  unions  is  a  good'  one. 
It  is  based  on  credit  capital,  or  the  use  of  character  and 
financial  standing  instead  of  cash  capital,  as  the  means  of 
obtaining  and  guaranteeing  the  funds  needed  by  members. 
The  credit  union  is  of  very  ancient  origin,  dating  back  to 
the  Middle  Ages  before  corporations  were  devised  and  when 
banking  was  done  individually  or  by  groups  of  men.  It  has 
always  proved  safe  and  effective  where  men  are  honest  and 
capable,  and  the  Central  Society  of  Agriculture  of  Belgium 
was  inclined  toward  this  method  around  1870  and  gave  seri- 
ous consideration  to  a  project  submitted  by  Mr.  Haeck  for 
the  establishment  of  an  elaborate  system  of  credit  unions 
composed  entirely  of  farmers  to  be  located  in  the  chief  cities 
of  aU  the  cantons. 

This  project,  however,  came  to  naught.  Cooperation  in 
its  true  form  had  made  its  appearance  about  a  decade  previ- 
ously and  eventually  became  recognized  as  the  best  means 
for  financing  farmers.  The  first  cooperative  credit  society 
in  Belgium  was  formed  by  Leon  d'Andrimont  at  Liege  in 
1864.  In  1865  others  were  formed  at  Verviers  and  Huy, 
in  1866  at  Gand,  and  in  1869  at  Namur  and  Saiat  Nicholas. 
In  1873  the  first  Belgian  law  on  cooperation  was  enacted, 
which,  as  amended  in  1886,  is  still  in  force.  In  1875  cooper- 
ative societies  were  exempted  from  various   stamp  duties. 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LUXEMBUEG,  ETC.    383 

taxes,  and  registration  fees.  A  few  more  societies  were  then 
formed,  and  all  the  existing  institutions  were  grouped  into 
a  federation  under  the  presidency  of  Mr.  d'Andrimont.  These, 
cooperative  credit  societies  were  of  the  Schulze-Delitzsch 
type.  They  have  now  dwindled  down  to  ahout  45,  of  which 
two,  at  Goe-Limburg  and  Argenteau,  respectively,  are  mainly 
agricultural.  In  1910  the  first  had  no  transactions,  while 
the  second  made  only  43  loans  to  farmers  of  a  total  of  only 
$11,283. 

The  failure  of  the  credit  unions  and  of  the  people's  or 
Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  to  extend  their  operations  to  farm- 
ers led  the  Government  to  intervene  in  1884  to  provide  other 
facilities  for  them.  In  that  year  a  law  was  passed  with  the 
object  of  making  the  General  Pension  and  Savings  Bank  the 
financial  head  for  agriculture  by  enlarging  the  powers  of 
the  concern  under  its  original  charter  so  as  to  permit  loans 
to  or  through  a  new  kind  of  institution  called  "comptoir 
agricole"  brought  into  existence  by  virtue  of  this  law.  A 
comptoir  is  a  body  of  at  least  three  persons  whose  sole  object 
is  to  guarantee  loans  granted  to  individual  farmers  by  the 
General  Pension  and  Savings  Bank.  In  other  words,  it  is, 
as  its  name  implies,  a  subsidiary  agricultural  counting-house 
of  the  Bank,  and  hopes  were  entertaiaed  that  through  its 
operation  as  a  local  agency,  the  Bank  would  be  able  to  make 
advances  in  safety  and  abundance  to  farmers  throughout  the 
country. 

This  idea  of  covering  the  country  with  local  comptoirs 
attached  to  a  central  bank  was  evidently  suggested  by  the 
abandoned  project  of  Frangois  Haeck,  although  there  are 
vital  points  of  difference  between  a  comptoir  and  a  Belgian 
credit  union.  Unlike  the  latter  the  comptoir  has  no  coopera- 
tive features  whatever  and  does  not  confine  its  services  to 
members.  True,  farmers  might  form  a  comptoir  to  guaran- 
tee loans  made  to  themselves  or  to  one  of  them  but  this  has 
never  been  done.  These  coimting-houses  are  formed  by  per- 
sons connected  or  at  least  in  sympathy  with  the  General 
Pension  and  Savings  Bank,  with  the  aim  of  protecting  its 
interests  and  obtaining  the  fees  it  allows.     The  fees  are  a 


384  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

del  credere  commission,  that  is,  paid  by  the  creditor  to  in- 
termediaries for  assuming  responsibility  for  the  money  lent. 
This  commission  is  now  three-fourths  of  one  per  cent  a  year 
on  the  amount  due  on  the  outstanding  loans,  a  compensation 
rather  small  for  doing  all  the  work,  assuming  all  the  expenses 
and  standing  responsible  for  all  losses  incurred  in  a  loan  or 
banking  business  consisting  of  small  sums  and  many  details, 
and  this  is  perhaps  the  reason  why  practically  only  long-term 
mortgages  are  now  taken.  In  1894  the  powers  of  the  Gen- 
eral Pension  and  Savings  Bank  were  again  extended  so  as 
to  permit  it  to  make  loans  to  cooperative  societies,  and  the 
Bank  thereupon  set  aside  $200,000  to  be  lent  at  S^^  per  cent 
to  cooperative  credit  societies  which  should  be  affliated  with 
their  own  central  banks. 

Nineteen  comptoirs  agricoles  have  been  formed,  15  of 
which  still  subsist.  They  had  indorsed  only  $3,757,146  to 
the  end  of  1910.  The  loans  were  for  sums  between  $300  and 
$10,000,  all  amply  secured.  The  larger  ones  ran  for  30  or 
more  years  and  were  reducible  by  annuities.  The  interest 
charged  borrowers  was  5.5  per  cent  and  the  bonds  secured  by 
these  loans  bore  interest  at  3.6  per  cent. 

The  General  Pension  and  Savings  Bank  is  gradually  los- 
ing its  importance  in  cooperation.  The  credit  societies 
and  central  bank  of  the  Boerenbond  have  no  relations  with 
it,  while  most  of  the  credit  societies  belonging  to  other  feder- 
ations have  ceased  to  depend  upon  it  because  they  are  able  to 
obtain  all  necessary  funds  through  their  own  central  banks. 
The  318  credit  societies,  indeed,  had  credit  accounts  with  it 
to  the  amount  of  $181,316  in  1910,  but  had  drawn  against 
these  only  $48,273. 

The  extension  of  the  powers  of  the  General  Pension  and 
Savings  Bank  so  as  to  enable  it  to  aid  agricultural  coopera- 
tion was  granted  upon  its  own  request  inspired  by  a  Catholic 
priest.  Father  Mellaerts.  In  1890  MeUaerts  organized  the 
Boerenbond,  or  Peasants'  League,  for  the  guidance  of  Belgian 
farmers  in  their  religious,  moral  and  material  affairs,  and 
under  its  auspices  he  founded  at  Eillaer  in  1893  the  first 
Eaiffeisen  bank  in  Belgium.    The  good  accomplished  through 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LU-XEMBURG,  ETC.    385 

his  enthusiasm  and  untiring  energies  soon  brought  him  to 
the  attention  of  Mr.  Mahillon,  the  president  of  the  Bank,  with 
the  result  that  Mr.  Mahillon  induced  the  Government  not 
only  to  make  the  changes  in  the  powers  of  his  hank,  but 
also  to  appropriate  a  fund  so  that  the  Belgian  Department  of 
Agriexdture  could  pay  the  cost  of  inspection  and  most  of  the 
organization  expenses  of  the  rural  credit  societies.  Twenty- 
five  dollars  is  now  given  to  each  new  society  duly  registered 
and  five  dollars  to  central  banks  for  each  local  society  affili- 
ated with  them. 

The  work  then  began  in  earnest,  and  today  cooperative 
banking  has  gained  a  strong  foothold  in  rural  Belgium.  It 
has  taken  the  syndical  direction  which  prevails  in  Prance, 
that  is,  the  farmers  form  syndicats,  and  then  as  members 
of  these  syndicats  form  local  societies  for  credit  and  other 
purposes,  so  that  the  cooperative  activities  in  every  locality 
are  closely  knit  together.  In  1912  there  were  272  farmers' 
syndicats  with  2,132  adhering  societies,  nearly  all  belonging 
to  49  federations.  Among  these  were  738  rural  cooperative 
societies  and  seven  central  banks.  The  538  credit  societies 
which  rendered  reports  to  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  in 
1910  had  at  the  close  of  that  year  27,334  members,  of  whom 
5,442  were  not  farmers.  The  total  of  outstanding  loans 
amounted  to  about  $2,291,014,  and  the  reserves  to  $93,831. 
The  deposits  with  the  entire  working  capital  amounted  to 
$4,582,457.  The  bulk  of  the  loans  were  for  $200  and  under. 
The  time  ran  from  100  days  up  to  ten  years.  Life  insur- 
ance is  sometimes  taken  for  security,  but  most  of  the  busi- 
ness is  done  on  the  indorsement  of  a  fellow  member.  Mort^ 
gages  are  required  for  the  long-term  loans,  which  are  in- 
variably reducible  by  instalments. 

The  Belgian  laws  allow  limited  or  unlimited  liability  but 
require  share  capital  and  forbid  the  accumulation  of  an  in- 
divisible reserve.  Consequently  the  rural  banks  cannot  be 
strictly  Eaiffeisen,  but  although  they  charge  entrance  fees 
(usually  one  franc),  they  adhere  as  closely  to  type  as  possi- 
ble by  making  both  shares  and  dividends  small.  Many  evade 
the  laws  further  by  dividing  their  surplus  into  halves.    The 


386  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

first  half  consists  of  the  profits  on  loans  made  out  of  deposits 
and  the  society's  own  funds,  and  is  retained  to  be  distributed 
only  in  case  of  dissolution.  The  second  half  is  created  partly 
from  the  same  source  and  partly  from  profits  on  advances 
received  from  its  central  bank,  and  is  held  to  be  turned  over 
to  the  latter  on  the  same  eventuality.  Collective  purchasing 
is  a  common  practice  with  the  local  credit  societies. 

The  local  banks  affiliate  with  central  banks  by  subscribing 
at  least  one  share,  usually  of  about  $30,  involving  a  liability 
limited  to  ten  times  the  amount  of  the  share.  They  obligate 
"themselves  to  keep  all  but  a  few  dollars  of  their  deposits  with 
the  central  bank,  and  also  to  submit  to  inspection  by  it.  The 
Boerenbond  or  Peasants'  League  founded  by  Father  Mellaerts 
at  Louvain,  a  Catholic  organization,  has  363,  or  nearly  one- 
half,  of  the  rural  credit  societies  of  Belgium,  and  all  are 
members  of  its  central  bank,  which  is  the  largest  of  the  seven. 
This  bank  has  a  land  section,  financed  by  bonds  bearing  3.6 
per  cent  interest,  which  lends  to  farmers  on  real-estate  mort- 
gages through  the  local  societies  at  4%  per  cent.  But  in  order 
to  get  money  for  this  purpose,  a  local  credit  society  must  sub- 
scribe one  share  of  ten  dollars  for  every  $100  advanced  to  it 
for  use  of  its  members. 

Agriculture  in  Holland  is  well  organized  by  means  of 
vUlage  associations  grouped  under  proviucial  federations, 
which  in  their  turn  are  bound  together  by  a  national  fed- 
eration. This  system  has  been  established  largely  through 
the  efforts  of  the  Catholic  clergy.  In  fact  it  was  started  by 
the  priests,  who  have  always  shown  great  activity  iu  advanc- 
ing the  economic  interest  of  the  farmers  and  to  this  end  have 
bent  their  energies  to  promote  various  forms  of  cooperation. 

In  1890  cooperation  was  little  known  among  the  Dutch 
farmers  although  a  cooperative  law  was  enacted  in  1876.  To- 
day it  has  reached  vast  proportions.  Its  development  has 
been  directly  encouraged  by  the  state  working  in  harmony 
with  the  Catholic  Church  and  private  initiative.  The  chief 
object  of  the  state  aid  has  been  the  improvement  of  the 
breed  of  cattle  and  the  creation  of  effective  credit  facilities. 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LUXEMBUKG,  ETC.    387 

The  first  cooperative  credit  society  in  HoUand  was  formed 
at  Maasbracht  in  Limburg  on  June  15,  1895.  The  second 
was  formed  the  following  year  at  Louneker.  Both  took  the 
Eaiffeisen  type,  as  did  all  societies  subsequently  formed,  and 
Holland  has  the  largest  and  purest  Eaiffeisen  system  outside 
of  Germany.  New  societies  registered  under  the  1876  law  are 
allowed  $30  by  the  state ;  if  registered  under  the  general  law 
on  associations  of  1855,  they  are  allowed  only  $3,  when  affili- 
ated with  a  central  bank.  In  1910  there  were  632  local 
credit  societies  in  Holland,  and  although  nearly  all  of  them 
owe  allegiance  to  the  Federation  of  Dutch  Peasants,  they  are 
divided  into  three  distinct  groups  under  the  central  banks 
at  Eindhoven,  Utrecht  and  Alkmaar,  by  which  they  are  regu- 
larly inspected  and  supervised. 

The  Eindhoven  central  bank  was  formed  ia  1896  by  the 
Peasants'  Christian  League  and  it  requires  all  members  of 
adhering  locals  to  be  Catholics.  Its  territory  lies  in  the 
southern  provinces.  It  operates  imder  the  law  of  1855  as  a 
limited-liability  association.  Its  members  are  local  credit 
societies  and  such  other  societies  as  may  be  incorporated  for 
the  advancement  of  agriculture.  The  shares  are  $400,  and 
each  adhering  society  must  take  at  least  one  and  pay  in  one 
per  cent  thereof.  After  the  share  has  been  entirely  paid  up 
the  liability  ceases. 

In  1910  the  Eindhoven  central  bank  had  283  adhering 
societies  with  21,959  members,  all  farmers.  Its  capital  was 
$222,400,  of  which  only  $2,616  was  paid  in.  The  reserves 
were  $30,000,  and  deposits  $1,708,145,  and  all  transactions 
amounted  to  $4,183,324.  The  interest  on  deposits  was  3.25 
per  cent,  and  that  on  loans  3.75  per  cent.  Its  subsidy  from 
the  state  was  $1,000. 

In  1908  the  Eindhoven  central  bank  established  the 
Peasants'  Cooperative  Mortgage  Bank  with  a  capital  of 
$400,000,  of  which  $80,000  was  subscribed  by  the  central  and 
locals.  This  Bank  grants  loans  at  4%  per  cent  for  40  years 
or  longer  on  condition  that  one  per  cent  of  the  principal  be 
paid  back  each  year.  It  finances  itself  by  issuing  bonds, 
and  paid  in  1910  a  dividend  of  21/^  per  cent. 


388  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  central  bank  at  Utrecht  was  organized  in  1898.  It 
is  imdenominational  and  admits  to  membership  societies 
■whose  members  are  not  farmers.  It  operates  principally 
in  that  part  of  Belginm  not  covered  by  the  Eindhoven  bank 
but  in  many  places  they  work  side  by  side.  In  1913  its 
capital  was  $174,800,  of  which  only  $10,712  was  paid  in.  The 
shares  are  $200.  Ten  per  cent  must  be  paid  in  on  the  first 
share,  but  on  others  only  ten  florins  ($4)  need  be  paid  at 
the  time  of  subscription.  The  liability  assumed  on  each 
share. is  $1,000.  Membership  is  confined  to  local  banks  and 
agricultural  societies  and  its  own  ofBcers.  Each  adherent 
must  subscribe  to  at  least  one  share  and  may  hold  a  maxi- 
mum of  ten  shares.  The  maximum  of  credit  which  may 
be  accorded  is  $4,000  for  each  share  held.  In  1912  the 
Utrecht  bank  received  a  subsidy  of  $1,360  from  the  state, 
and  at  the  close  of  that  year  it  had  439  adherents  with  21,941 
members.  Its  deposits  amounted  to  $2,601,139,  and  its  out- 
standing loans  to  the  locals  to  $654,636.  The  interest  rate 
on  deposits  was  3%  per  cent  at  the  highest,  and  on  loans 
414,  per  cent  at  the  lowest.  Por  adherents  which  kept  no 
deposits  with  the  bank  the  rate  of  interest  charged  was  5 
per  cent. 

The  Alkmaar  central  bank  was  founded  in  1901  by  dis- 
sidents from  the  Utrecht  central  bank,  and  occupies  the 
province  of  North  Holland,  or  a  portion  of  the  latter's  ter- 
ritory. The  2,466  members  of  its  32  adhering  locals  are 
mostly  Catholics.  It  is  a  pure  cooperative  body,  with  un- 
limited liability,  and  all  its  adherents  hold  equal  shares 
in  the  capital  and  profits.  In  1910  its  deposits  were  $109,943, 
drawing  3%^  per  cent,  and  its  loans  $41,062,  yielding  four  to 
4^  per  cent.  The  reserves  were  $2,772.  The  subsidy  received 
from  the  Government  was  $200. 

The  Government  assumes  all  the  expense  of  inspecting 
each  of  these  banks  above  $200  a  year.  The  late  statistics  of 
these  three  central  banks  are  very  incomplete,  but  show  that 
great  progress  has  been  made  in  the  past  four  years. 

In  the  little  Grand  Duchy  of  Luxemburg  there  are  only 
40,000  farms.    Half  of  them  have  less  than  2^  acres.     Of 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LUXEMBUEG,  ETC.    389 

the  rest,  16,000  farms  are  under  180  acres,  and  but  185 
farms  over  that  area.  Cooperation  has  naturally  reached  a 
high  degree  of  usefulness  in  the  midst  of  such  intensive 
cultivation.  Its  use,  however,  is  aU  for  collective  sales  and 
purchases.  There  are  no  cooperative  credit  societies.  Their 
place  is  filled  by  the  agricultural  and  people's  banks  estab- 
lished by  the  state. 

These  state  banks  serve  tradespeople,  employees  and  in- 
dustrials, as  well  as  farmers,  within  the  areas  assigned  to 
them.  They  came  into  existence  by  virtue  of  the  laws  of 
1900  and  1906.  They  are  formed  by  the  Government  upon 
request  of  the  municipal  councils.  The  credit  accorded  is 
strictly  personal.  A  loan  over  $200  or  for  longer  than  three 
years  can  be  granted  only  in  exceptional  cases,  and  then 
must  never  exceed  $400  for  five  years.  The  maximum  rate 
of  interest  is  five  per  cent.  The  rate  now  charged  is  four 
per  cent.  The  working  funds  are  supplied  by  the  Savings 
Bank  of  the  Grand  Duchy  at  a  rate  which  must  never  exceed 
four  per  cent. 

The  Savings  Bank  is  represented  in  the  administration 
of  every  one  of  these  little  banks,  and  in  ease  of  insufB- 
ciency  of  securities  given  for  its  advances,  may  demand  a 
guaranty  from  the  municipalities.  These  banks  now  number 
18.  The  customers  are  mostly  farmers,  but  so  far  very  little 
business  has  been  done.  In  1909  the  outstanding  loans 
amounted  to  only  about  $25,000. 

Cooperation  is  extensively  used  in  Denmark  for  collective 
buying  and  selling  of  farm  supplies  and  products  and  also 
for  long-term  credit  for  both  large  and  small  estates.  Co- 
operative credit  for  short  term  has  made  very  little  progress, 
although  as  far  back  as  1898  the  Government  intervened  di- 
rectly to  encourage  its  advancement.  In  that  year  a  law 
for  rural  cooperative  credit  societies  was  enacted  and  $1,340,- 
000  appropriated  to  be  loaned  among  societies  which  should 
be  created  in  accordance  with  its  provisions.  As  subsidy, 
however,  invariably  means  state  control  to  a  greater  or  less 
extent,  strict  rules  and  regulations  were  laid  down  for  the 


390  EUEAL    CREDITS 

organization  and  management  of  credit  societies,  and  this 
may  account  for  the  slowness  of  their  growth. 

A  rnral  cooperative  credit  society  under  this  law  must 
consist  of  at  least  50  farmers  residing  in  the  same  county 
and  owning  together  500  or  more  head  of  cattle.  The 
president  is  appointed  by  the  county  council,  and  the  amount 
the  society  may  receive  out  of  the  appropriation  is  deter- 
mined by  the  Agricultural  Commission,  which  is  the  oflBcial 
custodian  of  various  public  funds.  This  amount  must  be 
somewhere  between  the  values  of  1,000  and  10,000  head  of 
cattle,  unless  the  Ministry  of  Agriculture  permits  another 
figure.  This  advance  from  the  state  originally  bore  three 
per  cent  interest  and  was  required  to  be  repaid  in  1908,  when 
it  was  intended  that  the  entire  appropriation  should  be  re- 
called and  the  societies  left  to  stand  on  their  own  feet.  But 
in  that  year  the  law  was  amended  so  as  to  provide  that  only 
two-tenths  of  the  loan  should  then  be  repaid  and  one-tenth 
each  year  thereafter  from  1909  until  1916,  unless  otherwise 
provided  by  law.  In  consideration  of  giving  this  grace,  the 
rate  of  interest  was  raised  to  3^  per  cent  and  the  societies 
were  enjoined  against  charging  more  than  five  per  cent  to 
members. 

The  sole  object  of  the  societies  formed  under  the  1898 
law  is  to  guarantee  the  return  to  the  state  of  the  moneys 
which  were  advanced  by  it  and  to  see  that  they  are  put  to 
their  proper  use.  All  members  are  jointly  and  severally  liable 
to  the  state.  Loans  may  be  granted  only  to  members  and  for 
meeting  urgent  and  necessary  expenses  for  wages,  buying 
seed,  fertilizer  and  supplies,  and  the  upkeep  of  the  farm  and 
live  stock.  No  security  is  allowed  to  be  taken.  The  finan- 
cial standing  of  a  member  is  determined  by  the  registered 
cattle  he  owns,  and  the  extent  of  his  credit  is  $13.40  per 
head.  The  officers  receive  no  compensation,  and  all  gains 
are  placed  in  the  reserves,  which  may  be  used  for  loans  on  the 
same  terms  provided  for  those  made  from  the  state  subsidy. 
According  to  the  last  official  statistics  (1905),  there  were 
168  of  these  societies,  with  21,575  members  owning  161,710 
cattle  registered  on  the  societies'  books. 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LUXEMBUEG,  ETC.    391 

Norway  has  no  cooperative  banks  for  according  either 
long-term  or  short-term  credit.  A  few  societies  formed  for 
the  collective  buying  of  fodder  and  fertilizer  sometimes  make 
loans  to-  members.  The  mortgage-bond  companies,  of  which 
there  are  a  number,  make  many  loans  for  agricultural  pur- 
poses to  individuals  and  also  to  societies  which  are  willing  to 
pledge  the  mutual  liability  of  members  as  security.  But  the 
chief  source  of  credit  for  farmers  is  the  savings  banks.  These 
institutions  supply  the  well-to-do  farmers  vri.th  what  money 
they  need.  The  poor  classes  depend  on  the  Norwegian 
Bank  for  Laborers'  Holdings  and  Dwellings,  described  in  a 
previous  chapter. 

Agricultural  conditions  in  Sweden  are  similar  to  those 
in  Norway.  But  cooperation  is  extensively  practised  in 
Sweden,  as  the  idea  was  acclimatized  there  at  an  early 
date  by  the  landowners'  mortgage  associations.  In  1911  there 
were  5,869  Swedish  cooperative  associations,  agricultural 
and  industrial.  Only  23  of  them  had  credit  for  their  object, 
and  two  of  these  were  solely  urban.  A  new  cooperative  law, 
however,  was  enacted  in  1911,  which  makes  important 
changes  in  the  old  1895  law  on  economic  associations.  This 
new  legislation  has  given  a  strong  impetus  to  cooperative 
credit,  and  the  existing  societies  are  planning  to  establish 
a  central  bank,  while  a  campaign  has  been  started  for  local 
banks. 

Cooperative  credit  made  its  first  appearance  in  Switzer- 
land during  the  sixties  of  the  last  century  in  the  form  of 
people's  banks  similar  to  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  for 
industrials  and  shopkeepers  in  the  cities.  But  they  did  not 
conform  closely  to  type.  Some  of  them  had  imlimited  lia- 
bility and  others  limited  liability,  while  not  a  few  were  alto- 
gether without  capital,  its  place  being  supplied  by  the  guar- 
anty of  the  communes  or  benevolent  institutions.  They 
grew  in  numbers  with  the  progress  of  cooperation  generally, 
but  none  was  started  for  farmers  until  after  the  cooperative 
law  was  enacted  in  1883. 

The  first  rural  cooperative  credit  society  in  Switzerland 


393  RUEAL   CEEDITS 

was  foimded  at  Schlosslialde  in  the  vicinity  of  Berne  in 
1887  by  a  clergyman  named  Traber.  Another  was  formed 
the  same  year  by  Von  Steiger,  a  councillor  of  state,  but 
the  movement  did  not  become  active  until  1900  when  Traber 
formed  his  second  society  at  Biehelsee  in  Thurgau.  The 
first  society  was  composed  of  20  Christian  socialists,  and 
although  the  Swiss  laws  did  not  make  share  capital  obliga- 
tory, it  required  each  member  to  subscribe  to  a  share  of  50 
francs  ($10)  to  be  paid  up  in  instalments,  forbidding,  how- 
ever, any  member  to  hold  more  than  one  share.  This  share 
was  allowed  a  dividend  of  five  per  cent  out  of  the  profits  after 
50  per  cent  thereof  had  been  set  aside  for  the  indivisible  re- 
serve. After  the  reserve  reached  the  amount  of  the  liabilities 
of  the  society,  it  was  provided  that  the  net  annual  profits,  di- 
minished by  the  dividends,  should  be  devoted  to  some  object  of 
an  agricultural  or  industrial  nature  for  the  benefit  of  the 
members.  Barring  this  requirement  for  share  capital  and 
entrance  fees,  the  first  rural  cooperative  credit  societies  of 
Switzerland  were  replicas  of  the  German  Raiffeisen  societies, 
because  they  purchased  supplies  and  sold  produce  for  their 
members  and  looked  out  for  their  religious  and  moral  as  well 
as  material  welfare. 

By  1902  there  were  15  rural  cooperative  credit  societies, 
all  practically  like  the  first  which  was  founded.  Under  the 
direction  of  Traber  they  combined  and  formed  the  Swiss 
Union  of  Eaiffeisen  Banks,  which  subsequently  assiimed  the 
position  of  a  national  federation  and  brought  into  its  fold 
four  large  cantonal  unions.  But  the  right  of  supervising 
or  inspecting  its  adherents  has  not  been  conceded  to  it,  nor 
is  such  control  exercised  in  a  compulsory  way  by  the  can- 
tonal unions  or  any  other  authority.  Consequently  the 
statistics  which  have  been  gathered  are  not  sufficiently  full 
or  accurate  to  show  the  true  situation.  In  1910  there  were 
at  least  139  rural  cooperative  credit  societies  with  10,024 
members,  and  18  of  the  societies,  besides  receiving  deposits 
and  according  credit,  bought  and  sold  farm  supplies  and 
produce  in  the  true  Eaiffeisen  style.  In  that  year  all  but 
nine  of  the  societies  belonged  to  the  Swiss  Unions     The 


BELGIUM,  HOLLAND,  LUXEMBUEG,  ETC.    393 

business  done  amounted  to  around  $3,300,000.  In  1911 
tlie  affiliated  banks  had  increased  to  153  with  9,854  mem- 
bers, with  about  $9,000,000  of  business. 

Thus  cooperative  credit  has  gained  a  firm  foothold  in 
Switzerland,  but  the  idea  was  not  introduced  on  account  of 
any  lack  of  banking  facilities.  The  little  republic  has  been 
adequately  supplied  for  many  years  with  banks  which  reach 
all  classes  of  people,  and  she  is  frequently  referred  to  as 
the  only  country  in  which  farmers  have  too  much  credit. 
There  are  many  state,  communal,  private  and  small  joint- 
stock  banks  with  capital  of  a  few  thousand  dollars  each, 
which,  in  addition  to  receiving  deposits,  handle  discounts 
and  do  all  kinds  of  banking  business.  These  concerns  for 
over  two  score  years  have  been  collecting  petty  savings  and 
redistributing  them  in  their  respective  localities,  and  thus 
have  extended  banking  to  the  very  doors  of  the  rural  bor- 
rowers. ITecessity  did  not  bring  cooperative  credit  into 
being  in  Switzerland.  It  was  started  because  of  its  moral 
effect  in  teaching  farmers  to  be  their  own  bankers  and  to  be 
mutually  responsible  for  one  another. 

Besides  all  these  facilities  there  was  a  peculiar  form  of 
cooperative  credit  in  common  use  in  the  canton  of  Thurgau 
for  the  purchase  of  cattle,  long  before  the  regular  form  of 
cooperation  was  thought  of.  Indeed,  it  is  so  peculiar  that 
it  exists  in  no  other  country.  Cattle  raising  and  dairying 
are  the  chief  industry  of  this  canton,  the  inhabitants  in  some 
of  the  communes  being  nearly  all  devoted  to  it.  In  1851 
a  cantonal  law  was  enacted  authorizing  the  opening  of  com- 
munal offices  to  assist  farmers  financially  in  buying  cattle. 
These  offices  are  managed  by  a  commission  elected  by  pop- 
ular vote.  The  commission  may  borrow  money  for  its  pur- 
poses by  issuing  bonds  or  notes  upon  which  aU  of  the  elec- 
tors of  the  respective  communes  are  jointly  and  severally 
liable.  Hence  this  form  of  cooperation  is  in  a  measure 
voluntary.  The  farmer  who  obtains  a  loan  from  the  com- 
mission must  give  a  chattel  mortgage  on  the  cattle  pur- 
chased or  some  other  sufficient  security.  Sixty  dollars  is  the 
highest  sum  lent  on  one  head  of  cattle.     This  plan  soon 


394  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

proved  so  effective  that  the  cantonal  government  adopted 
the  practice  of  making  annual  appropriations  to  every  com- 
mune in  which  a  commission  is  established.  There  are  now 
at  least  35  cattle-purchasing  commissions  in  Thurgau,  and 
the  appropriations  with  the  accumulated  interest  thereon  and 
the  small  charges  added  to  the  borrowers'  interest,  have 
now  created  fimds  which  equal  the  outstanding  loans  of  the 
various  communes.  This  practice  has  been  adopted  in  other 
cantons,  notably  in  Zurich. 


CHAPTEE   XXVIII 

EUSSIA    AND    THE    BALKAN    STATES 

Activity  of  Cooperative  Societies  in  Eussia. — The  Artel. — Early  Co- 
operative Loan  and  Savings  Society. — Moscow  Agricultural  As- 
sociation.— Schulze-Delitzsch  Banks. — Credit  Societies. — General 
Board  for  Small  Credit  and  the  Bank  of  Eussia. — Legislation 
and  Government  Aid. — ^Zemstvo  Banks. — ^Moscow  People's 
Banks. — Conditions  in  Finland. — ^Highly  Centralized  Coopera- 
tion.— Central  Cooperative  Credit  Establishment. — People's 
Banks  in  Eoumania. — Central  Bank. — State  Aid. — Servian  Banks 
of  Eaiffeisen  Type. — Joint-stock  Central  Bank. — General  Union. 
— ^Public  Granaries. — Farmers'  Banks  of  Bulgaria. — Central  Ag- 
ricultural Bank. — Unique  Central  Cooperative  Bank. — Coopera- 
tive Attempts  in  Turkey  iand  Cyprus. — Cooperation  Among  Jew- 
ish Colonists  in  Palestine. 

The  mighty  empire  of  Eussia  comprises  many  races 
which  differ  one  from  another  in  language,  customs  and 
local  laws,  while  all  degrees  of  intelligence  down  to  unlet- 
tered ignorance  are  found  among  its  numerous  rural  popu- 
lation. The  rural  population  of  European  Eussia  is  the  more 
enlightened,  yet  the  bulk  of  even  the  European  farmers  were 
serfs  bound  to  the  soil  as  late  as  1861.  They  emerged 
from  bondage  without  land  or  the  means  to  buy  it,  but  behind 
them  lay  the  vast,  desolate  steppes  of  the  interior  which  have 
now  become  the  granary  of  two  continents.  The  organiza- 
tion of  credit  in  such  a  nation  naturally  followed  various 
lines,  and  much  of  it  bears  the  stamp  of  an  autocratic  govern- 
ment solicitous  for  the  welfare  of  a  people  whom  it  looks  upon 
as  its  wards.  Nevertheless,  Eussia  is  second  only  to  Ger- 
many in  the  number  of  its  cooperative  societies  and  sur- 
passes all  the  world  in  the  rapidity  of  the  progress  which 
it  is  making  in  the  advancement  of  cooperative  credit. 

395 


396  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  earliest  form  of  association  in  Eussia  was  the  artel, 
sometimes  temporary  in  character  and  sometimes  more  like 
a  guild  composed  of  persons  of  the  same  class,  bound  to- 
gether under  the  leadership  of  a  chief  for  mutual  assistance 
and  defense.  Formerly  the  artels  were  without  written  rules 
or  regulations.  They  now  exist  in  unknown  numbers,  and 
many  of  them  operate  under  signed  articles  of  agreement; 
they  have  millions  of  dollars  at  their  disposal  in  the  banks. 
The  more  influential  artels  charge  large  entrance  fees,  but 
have  no  trouble  in  getting  new  members  because  they  take  care 
of  all  who  are  out  of  woik  if  employment  cannot  be  found. 

Members  frequently  own  little  farms  on  which  they  live 
a  part  of  the  year,  but  the  artel  is  not  for  landowners.  It 
owes  its  origin  to  the  habit  of  the  unencumbered  laborers 
and  peasantry  of  pulling  up  stakes  and  migrating  in  droves 
from  their  old  homes  to  more  attractive  regions  on  the  broad, 
easily  traveled  prairies  of  the  Eussian  hinterland.  While 
extending  financial  aid  in  times  of  need,  very  few  artels  have 
gone  into  the  credit  or  bankiag  business.  Those  which  have 
adapted  themselves  to  modern  conditions  became  economic 
cooperative  societies  or  labor  unions.  Hence  the  Eussian 
peasants  were  compelled  to  find  other  forms  of  association  for 
credit  purposes. 

In  1840  the  communes  created  loan  funds  and  organized 
a  few  provident  savings  banks,  but  these  had  no  coopera- 
tive feature  and  were  simply  a  method  adopted  with  the  view 
of  getting  banking  dovm  to  the  people.  The  first  mutual 
credit  society  iu  Eussia  was  foimded  in  1864  in  the  city  of 
St.  Petersburg.  The  next  year  S.  P.  Longuinine,  imbued 
with  the  spirit  of  Eaifleisen,  started  a  savings  and  loan  so- 
ciety, which  was  soon  followed  by  others  in  a  number  of 
rural  communities.  In  1866  a  cooperative  loan  and  savings 
society  with  shares  payable  by  annual  instalments  was  founded 
at  Dorovatovo.  This  model  met  with  the  approval  of  the 
Moscow  Agricultural  Association,  -^hich  formed  a  perma- 
nent commission  to  propagate  the  idea.  The  cooperative 
movement  may  be  said  to  have  begun  in  that  year. 

Officials  of  the  provincial  and  district  governments  were 


EUSSIA  AND  THE  BALKAN"  STATES       397 

numerous  and  influential  in  the  commission,  and  this  led  to 
state  intervention  in  the  movement  which  has  continued 
in  an  increasing  measure  down  to  the  present  day.  The 
entering  wedge  was  an  appropriation  of  $3,600  out  of  the 
Imperial  Treasury  to  the  Moscow  Agricultural  Association 
for  educational  work.  Next  the  provinces  and  districts  sub- 
vened cooperative  societies,  and  many  were  formed  through 
these  forced  means,  but  as  the  mass  of  the  farmers  did  not 
join,  the  progress  was  artificial.  The  members  were  mainly 
persons  in  comfortable  circumstances  who  borrowed  the  cheap 
money  to  lend  at  a  profit  to  third  parties.  In  1888  as 
many  as  395  of  these  spoon-fed  societies  went  to  the  wall. 

But  in  spite  of  these  failures  cooperation  took  root,  and  in 
1895  it  was  deemed  advisable  to  enact  a  law  to  give  it  a 
legal  status.  This  law  authorized  the  formation  of  coopera- 
tive credit  societies  with  and  without  shares,  but  forbade  so- 
cieties without  share  capital  to  receive  deposits  from  out- 
side sources.  These  were  intended  to  serve  as  locals,  while 
societies  with  shares  were  designed  as  regional  banks,  but 
this  distinction  was  not  observed  in  practice.  The  share 
societies  were  organized  and  managed  according  to  the 
Schulze-Delitzsch  principles  and  recruited  their  members 
mostly  from  the  cities,  while  the  Eaiffeisen  societies  which 
Longuinine  and  his  followers  had  formed  practically  all 
disappeared  as  soon  as  they  were  deprived  of  their  main 
source  of  outside  capital,  because  the  members  themselves 
were  too  poor  to  make  deposits  in  sufficient  volume  for  their 
operations.  Consequently  the  peasantry  was  left  without  a 
credit  system  of  its  own. 

An  effort  to  remedy  this  situation  was  made  in  1904  by 
enacting  a  law  on  "small  credit  institutions."  A  smaU 
credit  institution,  according  to  this  law,  is  one  which, 
whether  cooperative  or  not,  fixes  the  maximum  at  $156  for 
ordinary  loans  and  at  $520  for  loans  secured  by  mortgage 
on  grain.  Special  privileges  were  accorded  institutions  of 
this  kind,  and  they  grew  and  spread  very  rapidly  until  1910, 
when  Eussian  legislation,  having  passed  through  its  experi- 
mental stages,  finally  culminated  in  a  cooperative  credit 


398  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

law  based  on  true  principles.  No  new  small  credit  institu- 
tion has  been  formed  since  that  year  and  although  the, 
4,809  still  existing,  with  balance  sheets  showing  $38,546,172, 
loom  large  on  paper,  they  are  of  no  economic  importance  in 
rural  life  and  are  in  fact  in  liquidation. 

The  types  of  cooperative  credit  societies  now  in  active 
operation  in  Eussia  are  people's  or  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks 
and  cooperative  loan  and  savings  societies.  The  main  points 
of  difference  between  the  two  are  that  the  latter  have  no 
share  capital  and  pay  no  dividends.  In  1913  there  were 
3,300  people's  banks  in  Eussia.  The  3,019  which  rendered 
reports  had  1,736,301  members.  Their  share  capital 
amounted  to  $23,662,575,  special  capital  to  $1,919,930,  re- 
serves to  $3,574,910,  deposits  to  $87,283,230,  money  bor- 
rowed to  $10,073,915,  and  outstanding  loans  to  $109,193,390. 
The  great  majority  of  their  members  were  industrials,  trades- 
people and  urban  residents. 

The  cooperative  savings  and  loan  societies,  on  the  other 
hand,  are  all  agricultural,  but  they  conform  in  no  sense  of 
the  word  to  the  Eaiffeisen  type.  The  board  of  management 
of  every  society  is  always  paid,  the  liability  of  members 
in  the  majority  of  cases  is  limited,  and  the  size  of  the  society 
is  large.  The  average  membership  is  607,  the  operations 
often  extend  over  large  areas  embracing  2,000  to  4,000 
households,  and  the  loans  are  never  granted  for  longer  than 
a  year.  Nor  do  they  teach  religion,  or  as  a  rule  make  col- 
lective purchases  or  sales  for  members.  So  the  Eussian 
rural  cooperative  savings  and  loan  societies,  instead  of  being 
like  Eaiffeisen's,  are  sui  generis. 

According  to  the  law,  each  credit  society  must  have  at  the 
start  a  social  fund  of  not  less  than  $530,  which  may  be  cre- 
ated either  by  donation,  borrowed  money  or  members'  sub- 
scriptions. This  fund  must  never  be  allowed  to  fall  below 
its  original  amount,  and  must  be  increased  each  year  by 
40  per  cent  of  the  profits.  Twenty  per  cent  of  the  rest  of  the 
profits  go  into  the  reserves.  Although  no  dividends  are  per- 
mitted, a  portion  of  the  remainder  may  be  distributed  as  a 
rebate  among  members,  if  so  decided  at  their  annual  meet- 


ETJSSIA  AND  THE  BALKAN  STATES        39» 

ing.  The  assets  left  after  dissolution  of  a  society  are  de- 
voted to  some  beneTolent  object.  If  a  society  is  formed 
with  capital,  the  size  of  the  shares  may  be  fixed  at  one  or 
two  rubles  (one  ruble,  61%  cents)  up  to  a  hundred  or  so 
rubles  payable  by  periodical  instalments.  But  voting  is  per 
head  and  not  per  share,  so  no  matter  how  many  shares  a 
member  may  be  allowed  to  hold,  he  may  cast  but  one  ballot 
at  any  election  or  on  any  resolution. 

In  1913  the  total  number  of  savings  and  loan  coopera- 
tive societies  in  Eussia,  excluding  Finland,  was  9,200.  The 
7,974  societies  rendering  reports  had  4,867,734  members. 
Their  social  funds  amounted  to  $13,653,035,  special  funds  ta 
$2,148,125,  reserves  to  $1,824,645,  deposits  to  $60,997,630, 
and  borrowed  money  to  $36,449,885.  The  outstanding  loans 
were  $95,215,260.  The  interest  on  deposits  was  between 
five  and  eight  per  cent.  The  interest  on  loans  was  high, 
according  to  cooperative  standards.  In  new  societies  it  was 
generally  13  per  cent  and  the  lowest  rate  was  10  per  cent. 
-This  rather  heavy  rate  is  due  to  the  lack  of  money  in  Eussia 
and  is  considerably  below  what  is  exacted  from  farmers  not- 
belonging  to  cooperative  societies. 

Including  Finland,  there  were  in  1913  at  least  ISjSOO- 
Eussian  people's  banks  and  cooperative  savings  and  loan 
societies,  with  a  membership  near  to  8,000,000,  and  the  foot- 
ings of  their  balance  sheets  showed  a  combined  amount  of 
$243,050,000.  Very  few  of  these  concerns  do  collective  buy- 
ing and  selling,  but  at  least  1,670  of  the  rural  societies  have 
erected  and  financed  granaries  for  storing  and  marketing 
wheat. 

There  are  11  federations  of  cooperative  credit  societies 
and  banks  in  Eussia.  They  have  not  the  right  of  compul- 
sory audit  or  supervision  over  their  adherents  and  conse- 
quently do  not  exercise  much  influence  upon  their  affairs. 
The  greatest  directing  power  over  the  societies  is  the  Govern- 
ment itself.  All  societies  not  belonging  to  the  Schnlze- 
Delitzsch  federations  have  been  welded  together  into  a 
highly  centralized  system  under  the  control  of  the  Imperial 
Government,  the  natural  corollary  of  the  state  aid  it  enjoys. 


400  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

This  control  is  exercised  through  the  Imperial  bank  of  issue, 
the  Bank  of  Eussia,  for  which  an  agricultural  programme 
■was  inaugurated  as  early  as  1896.  The  law  of  1904  pur- 
suant to  this  programme  provided  for  the  creation  of  a 
■General  Board  for  Small  Credit  within  the  Bank  of  Eussia. 

The  president  of  this  Board  is  selected  from  among  the 
■directors  of  the  Bank,  and  its  executive  committee  consists 
of  this  president,  the  vice-presidents,  representatives  of  the 
Imperial  auditor's  office  and  of  the  Departments  of  Agricul- 
"ture,  the  Interior  and  the  Treasury,  and  a  few  other  public 
officials.  The  Board  is  charged  with  the  distribution  of  sub- 
sidies, and  its  duties  are  to  audit  and  supervise  small  credit 
institutions,  cooperative  societies  included,  and  to  adjust  the 
Telations  between  them  and  the  Bank  of  Eussia.  The  Board 
lias  a  right  to  the  services  of  the  Bank's  inspectors,  and 
through  these  semi-public  officers  and  provincial  or  district 
■committees,  it  promotes  qpoperative  and  people's  credit  and 
sees  that  all  the  institutions  under  its  Jurisdiction  conduct 
themselves  in  strict  conformity  with  the  laws.  By  a  law 
of  1910  the  savings  banks  were  required  each  year  to  invest 
ien  per  cent  of  the  increase  of  their  deposits  over  the  pre- 
ceding year  in  loans  to  the  institutions  for  small  credit. 
These  sums  are  distributed  by  this  Board  among  the  coop- 
erative credit  societies  for  enlarging  their  social  funds. 

Through  this  machinery  the  Bank  of  Eussia  has  loaned 
$57,514,170  to  12,237  cooperative  credit  societies  (1913). 
But  this  is  only  a  small  portion  of  what  the  Bank  of  Eussia 
las  invested  in  agricultural  loans.  The  Bank  has  assisted 
agriculture,  especially  for  moving  grain,  since  1885  by  ex- 
tending credit  on  growing  crops  or  on  warrants  or  waybills 
of  grain  in  storage  or  in  transit,  to  the  farmers  directly  or 
through  their  credit  institutions  or  the  railroads.  In  1911 
13  per  cent  of  its  loan  and  discount  business  was  done  on  this 
security  and  six  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the  grain  crop  of 
the  whole  country  was  mortgaged  to  it  in  this  way.  The 
credit  ran  for  one  year  or  under  at  an  average  of  4.5  per 
cent  interest  without  any  commissions  or  charges  for  travel- 
ing expenses.    The  Bank  of  Eussia  also  makes  loans  on  real 


EUSSIA  AND  THE  BALKAN   STATES        401 

estate  and  on  the  farmers'  personal  paper  for  implements- 
and  machines. 

Not  only  has  Russia  surpassed  all  European  nations  in 
expenditures  and  concessions  for  creating  small  holdings  for 
peasants,  but  she  has  now  taken  foremost  rank  in  providing' 
credit  facilities  for  farmers  both  large  and  small.  In  1909 
Eussia  enacted  a  law  for  the  erection  of  84  public  granaries; 
to  be  completed  by  1916.  Eight  of  these  were  in  operation 
in  1913j  constructed  of  reinforced  concrete  in  American 
style.  The  farmers  have  no  difficulty  in  borrowing  money  at 
cheap  rates  against  receipts  issued  by  these  granaries.  The 
Eussian  Government  time  and  again  has  also  made  heavy 
appropriations  to  succor  farmers  in  regions  devastated  by 
droughts  or  revolutions.  Some  notable  instances  occurred 
during  the  bad  crops  of  1898,  1906  and  1911.  In  these  years 
public  funds  were  placed  at  the  disposal  of  the  Minister  of 
the  Interior,  who  employed  them  in  purchasing  seed  and 
other  agricultural  necessities  or  in  making  loans  to  the 
provinces  and  districts  for  such  purchases  to  be  distributed 
among  suffering  farmers.  These  advances  were  intended  to 
be  provisional  but  only  a  few  of  them  have  been  repaid. 
Less  than  two  per  cent  of  the  $395,820,254  thus  lent  between 
1891  and  1912  has  been  recovered.  The  Government  occa- 
sionally cancels  outstanding  claims  and  pockets  the  loss. 

The  provinces  and  other  territorial  divisions  of  Eussia 
have  been  no  less  active  than  the  Imperial  Government  in 
providing  credit  facilities  for  farmers.  At  the  beginning  of 
1912  there  were  1,405  county  credit  and  savings  banks 
founded  by  villages  or  groups  of  tenant  farmers.  A  law  of 
1905  authorizes  the  county  to  establish  these  banks  on  the 
vote  of  a  two-thirds  majority  of  the  electors  concerned.  In 
addition  there  were  seven  federations  embracing  105  credit 
organizations  and  also  107  zemstvo  people's  banks.  The 
latter  are  simply  departments  of  the  zemstvos  (districts), 
without  members,  but  established  upon  the  vote  of  a  two- 
thirds'  majority  of  the  electors.  Over  one-half  of  their  busi- 
ness is  transacted  with  cooperative  credit  societies,  and  com- 
prises both  long-term  loans  for  creating  or  enlarging  their 


402  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

capital  and  short-term  loans  for  supplying  them  with  work- 
ing funds.  The  interest  rate  is  between  seven  and  eight 
per  cent  for  societies  and  between  nine  and  12  per  cent  for 
individuals.  Some  of  the  zemstvo  banks  maintain  stores  for 
the  sale  on  credit  of  fertilizers,  farm  implements  and  metal 
loofing. 

All  these  regional  institutions  use  cooperative  methods. 
Besides  those  mentioned  there  were  3,792  credit  establish- 
ments owned,  managed,  controlled  and  financed  by  various 
local  authorities.  Among  these  are  savings  and  subsidy 
banks,  banks  for  ex-serfs  of  the  public  domains,  village  banks 
operating  with  revenues  obtained  from  liquor  licenses,  etc., 
rural  banks  formed  by  popular  vote  of  one  or  more  counties, 
communal  savings  banks,  orphans'  banks  of  which  the  fimds 
are  lent  to  farmers,  and  special  banks  for  Poland  and  for 
certain  natives. 

State  aid,  indeed,  is  playing  the  most  important  part  in 
the  organization  of  cooperative  credit  in  Eussia.  But  this 
intervention  does  not  extend  to  giving  special  privileges  or 
free  grants  of  money  except  in  event  of  extreme  necessity. 
It  rests  at  making  loans  on  reasonable  terms  and  interest 
rates.  The  cooperatives  understand  this  to  be  the  case,  and 
they  have  already  established  two  central  banks  to  take  the 
place  of  the  Bank  of  Eussia  and  the  General  Board  for  Small 
Credit  when  the  temporary  aid  which  the  credit  societies 
are  now  enjoying  shall  be  vidthdrawn.  The  first  of  these  cen- 
tral institutions  is  the  Warsaw  Cooperative  Bank  founded 
in  1910.  At  its  foundation  1,301  of  its  shares  were  sub- 
scribed by  private  individuals,  1,717  by  establishments  of 
popular  credit,  611  by  72  people's  banks,  193  by  four  indus- 
trial credit  banks,  97  by  17  agricultural  associations,  44  by 
13  distributive  cooperative  societies,  and  37  by  various  other 
societies.  In  1912,  3,000  more  shares  were  issued  and  im- 
mediately subscribed,  and  the  capital  now  stands  at  $901,250. 

The  second  is  the  Moscow  People's  Bank  founded  in  1911. 
It  did  not  have  to  resort  to  a  public  issue  of  shares.  Its 
first  3,822  shares  were  taken  up  as  follows :  80  by  23  estab- 
lishments of  popular  credit;  1,399  by  701  cooperative  credit 


EUSSIA  AND  THE  BALKAN   STATES        403 

societies;  678  by  290  people's  banks;  63  by  13  urban  credit 
and  savings  societies;  31  by  four  federations  of  cooperative 
credit;  57  by  two  federations  of  artel  creameries;  81  by  42 
cooperative  creameries;  200  by  the  Muscovite  Union  of  Dis- 
tributive Cooperative  Societies;  491  by  227  distributive  co- 
operative societies;  53  by  18  agricultural  cooperative  socie- 
ties; 38  by  nine  credit  and  mutual  aid  societies;  35  by  nine 
exchange  artels;  four  by  two  cooperative  associations;  eight 
by  four  groups  of  popular  credit  establishments;  and  605  by 
160  individual  cooperatives.  In  1913  it  issued  4,000  new 
shares,  and  its  paid-up  capital  is  now  $515,000. 

The  Grand  Duchy  of  Finland,  unlike  the  other  provinces 
of  Eussia,  is  autonomous  as  regards  internal  affairs.  Co- 
operation has  progressed  there  independently  of  the  move- 
ment in  the  rest  of  the  Empire.  This  northwestern  extremity 
of  Eussia  is  a  vast,  marshy  plateau  with  a  cold,  moist  climate. 
Eighty  per  cent  of  its  3,600,000  inhabitants  are  farmers  and 
foresters,  who  14  years  ago  were  poor  and  ignorani  and 
understood  very  little  about  modern  methods  of  cultivation. 

This  backward  condition  had  long  been  viewed  with  con- 
cern by  the  educated  portion  of  the  population.  In  1890 
some  magazine  articles  and  pamphlets  appeared  in  the  Fin- 
nish and  Swedish  languages  on  English  and  Danish  coopera- 
tion and  the  Eaiffeisen  cooperative  credit  societies.  These 
awakened  widespread  interest,  and  in  1899  some  college  pro- 
fessors and  lawyers  formed  an  association  for  introducing 
cooperation  into  Finland.  In  the  foUovring  year  they  had 
a  law  passed  on  cooperation  which  went  into  effect  in  1901, 
and  thereupon  they  started  a  campaign  for  cooperation  which 
has  continued  with  increasing  energy  to  the  present.  This 
propagandist  association  is  now  composed  of  over  1,000  of  the 
best  citizens  of  Finland,  and  is  maintained  by  private  con- 
tributions and  the  sales  of  periodicals  which  it  publishes. 
But  its  greatest  asset  is  the  enthusiastic  and  voluntary  sup- 
port of  young  professors  of  the  agricultural  and  other  col- 
leges who  spend  their  vacations  in  lecturing  and  organiza- 
tion work.  Since  the  Finnish  farmers  seem  to  lack  the  nec- 
essary initiative  to  take  matters  in  their  own  hands,  all 


404  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

inspiration  has  emanated  from  this  one  association,  and  hence 
the  cooperative  system  which  is  being  developed  has  become 
highly  centralized  and  every  society  so  far  formed  has 
joined  it. 

Butter-maktng  and  collective  buying  and  selling  were  the 
first  subjects  to  which  this  central  association  directed  its 
attention.  The  next  was  credit,  and  in  1902,  upon  learn- 
ing that  the  Grand  Duke  favored  the  project,  a  few  associates 
founded  a  bank  under  the  name  of  the  "Central  Cooperative 
Credit  Establishment."  These  associates  subscribed  for  all 
the  capital  of  $60,000  on  the  understanding  that  they  would 
sell  their  shares  to  local  credit  societies  whenever  the  latter 
cared  to  buy.  The  state  of  Finland  advanced  $800,000  as  a 
working  fund  and  granted  an  annual  subsidy  of  $4,000  for 
ten  years.  A  new  advance  of  $1,000,000  has  been  asked  for. 
The  bank  is  a  private  institution  managed  by  six  directors 
and  an  executive  council  of  which  the  president  is  selected  as 
the  head. 

The  Central  Cooperative  Credit  Establishment  extends 
credit  not  to  individuals  but  only  to  societies  in  proportion 
to  the  amount  of  stock  they  hold.  Its  loans  are  made  on 
open  accounts,  against  which  adherents  may  draw  up  to  the 
maximum  allowed  for  any  sums  large  or  small,  and  they  may 
make  repayments  without  giving  any  previous  notice,  that  is, 
a  cash  credit  business  is  carried  on.  The  size  of  loans  which 
have  been  granted  runs  from  $200  to  $12,000.  The  interest 
Tate  is  between  four  and  five  per  cent. 

In  1913  there  were  about  2,000  local  cooperative  societies 
with  nearly  250,000  members  in  Finland.  The  credit  so- 
cieties are  similar  to  those  of  the  Eussian  system  in  that  they 
have  no  shares  and  pay  no  dividends.  They  are  not  per- 
mitted under  the  law  to  take  deposits  from  outsiders,  and 
inasmuch  as  members  are  usually  too  poor  to  make  deposits 
in  quantity,  the  societies  have  to  depend  upon  the  Central 
Establishment.  The  money  borrowed  from  this  institution  is 
loaned  out  to  members  at  5.5  and  six  per  cent.  Near  the 
Russian  border  a  commission  of  one-half  of  one  per  cent  to 
two  per  cent  is  added. 


EUSSIA   AND    THE    BALKAN    STATES      405 

Cooperation  appeared  in  the  cities  of  Eoumania  about 
1880  in  the  form  of  people's  banks,  but  it  did  not  make  much 
headway  until  after  1895  when  it  began  to  be  used  by  the 
farmers.  By  1902  there  were  700  cooperative  credit  associa- 
tions with  59,618  members.  This  evidence  of  strength  and 
efficacy  caused  Eoumania  the  next  year  to  enact  a  law  on 
cooperation  and  also  to  found  the  Central  Bank  for  People's 
Banks  and  Cooperative  Societies,  with  a  capital  of  $4,000,000 
supplied  by  the  state. 

In  1911  there  were  3,750  cooperative  banks  with  510,118 
members  in  Eoumania.  Their  capital  was  $15,361,307,  of 
which  $13,450,648  had  been  paid  in.  The  deposits  were 
$2,558,604,  and  outstanding  loans  $19,593,000.  The  law 
allows  25  persons  to  form  a  bank,  but  the  average  member- 
ship was  185.  Shares  in  the  same  bank  may  be  unequal,  and 
they  run  from  $4  up  to  $1,000.  Twenty  or  30  of  the  banks 
impose  unlimited  liability,  but  all  the  rest  limit  the  liability 
of  members  to  the  amount  of  their  subscriptions.  Each 
bank  confines  itself  to  a  village  or  a  city,  and  it  receives 
deposits  from  and  grants  loans  to  any  person  withia  its  area. 
In  fact,  about  one-third  of  the  loans  are  granted  to  non- 
members.  Members,  however,  are  forbidden  to  deal  with 
any  other  bank.  A  very  large  number  of  the  banks  do  col- 
lective buying  and  selling.  Much  of  the  aid  secured  from  the 
state  is  used  in  making  loans  to  members. 

The  banks  do  not  accord  credit  for  a  longer  period  ia  the 
first  instance  than  six  or  nine  months.  If  a  borrower  needs 
more  time  a  renewal  may  be  granted,  but  never  for  over 
18  months,  unless  the  shareholders  at  a  regular  meeting 
decide  otherwise.  Collateral  and  chattel  mortgages  are  fre- 
quently taken,  but  the  preferred  security  is  the  indorsement 
of  one  or  two  responsible  friends.  The  interest  charged  non- 
members  is  nine  or  13  per  cent.  Members  obtain  credit  at  a 
few  points  lower. 

The  management  of  a  bank  is  entrusted  to  an  executive 
coimcil  of  six  or  nine  members  elected  for  three  years,  one- 
third  of  whom  retire  annually.  In  the  small  societies  the 
council  serves  without  pay.    In  the  larger  ones,  15  per  cent  of 


406  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

tlie  year's  profits  is  distributed  among  its  members  and  used 
for  meeting  administrative  expenses.  The  highest  dividend 
is  ten  per  cent.  The  surplus  is  written  off  to  the  reserves. 
This  fund,  which  in  1912  amounted  to  $3,000,000,  must  be 
invested  in  government  bonds. 

There  are  20  federations  to  which  400  cooperative  banks 
belong,  but  their  central  institution  is  still  the  Central  Bank 
for  People's  Banks  and  Cooperative  Societies  whose  manage- 
ment is  controlled  by  the  state.  This  Bank  exercises  a  strict 
supervision  over  the  local  banks  and  requires  them  to  con- 
form with  its  methods  of  doing  business  but  in  other  respects 
gives  them  entire  freedom  of  action.  It  advances  money  to 
them  at  four  or  five  per  cent. 

State  aid  is  a  dominant  feature  of  the  agricultural  credit 
system  of  Eoumania.  Besides  the  Central  Bank,  there  are 
three  other  state  banks  subsidized  and  managed  by  the 
Government.  These  were  called  into  existence  with  the  ob- 
ject of  furnishing  persons  engaged  in  agriculture  with  the 
necessary  means  to  buy  and  equip  farms  on  the  public  domain 
and  on  estates  of  large  landowners,  which  have  been  ordered 
to  be  sold  and  subdivided  for  small  holdings.  Their  busi- 
ness has  thus  a  special  character  and  relates  primarily  to 
real  estate.  The  agricultural  section  of  one  of  them,  how- 
ever, is  very  active  in  according  short-term  credit.  This  is 
the  Agricultural  Credit  Bank  established  in  1899,  before  the 
state  had  provided  cooperation  with  its  own  central  institu- 
tion. The  $4,000,000  which,  like  its  successor,  it  received 
from  the  state,  has  been  placed  at  the  disposal  of  the  coop- 
erative credit  associations  for  discounting  the  bills  and  notes 
of  their  members  and  customers.  The  Agricultural  Credit 
Bank  has  been  charged  also  with  the  duty  of  collecting  the 
$7,027,668  which  the  state  advanced  to  the  farmers  for  food 
and  grain  during  the  famine  in  1904  and  1905.  Its  officers, 
moreover,  are  identical  with  those  of  the  Agricultural  Credit 
Bank,  which  was  organized  in  1906  with  a  capital  of  $400,000 
to  be  used  in  loans  on  easy  terms  to  vintners  for  re- 
storing and  replanting  vineyards  damaged  by  the  ravages  of 
phylloxera. 


EUSSIA    AND    THE    BALKAN    STATES      407 

The  first  cooperative  bank  in  Servia  -vras  foimded  by  one 
Avramovitch  at  Vranovo  ia  the  Danube  Department  on 
March  29,  1894.  By  1911  there  were  ia  existence  907  banks. 
The  reports  of  536  showed  37,469  members  and  a  business  of 
$3,234,838.  These  banks  are  all  of  the  Eaiffeisen  type  with 
some  slight  changes  due  to  local  conditions. 

The  territory  of  a  bank  is  confined  to  an  area  embracing 
1,000  to  3,000  inhabitants.  There  is  very  little  distinction 
between  shares  and  deposits.  The  payments  made  on  shares 
are  considered  as  permanent  savings,  while  deposits  are 
looked  upon  as  funds  for  daily  use,  placed  with  the  bank 
simply  for  safekefeping,  after  the  fashion  adopted  by  Mr. 
Desjardins  for  'Quebec,  described  in  a  subsequent  chapter. 
The  share  is  an  obligation  to  pay  monthly  sums  during  a 
certain  period,  usually  ten  or  30  cents  a  month  for  two,  three 
or  five  years.  After  they  are  fully  paid  up  they  are  redeem- 
able with  4%  or  six  per  cent  interest,  as  fixed  at  the  annual 
meeting  of  the  members.  The  payments  on  these  shares  con- 
stitute the  social  capital  of  the  bank,  and  there  is  no  regula- 
tion as  to  the  number  of  shares  which  may  be  held  ia  one 
hand,  nor  is  there  need  of  any,  since  voting  is  done  not  per 
share  but  per  member.  No  dividends  are  distributed.  What- 
ever profits  remain  after  setting  aside  the  amounts  deter- 
mined for  the  reserves  are  turned  over  to  the  central  bank. 
Reserves  also  would  be  similarly  disposed  of  in  the  event  of 
dissolution. 

A  lower  rate  of  interest  is  given  on  deposits  than  on 
the  savings  used  in  buying  shares,  but  every  effort  is  made 
to  attract  deposits.  Pennies  are  received,  and  a  special 
service  has  been  opened  in  most  of  the  banks  for  school 
children  whose  mites  are  collected  by  means  of  stamps  pur- 
chased and  pasted  on  cards.  Many  of  the  banks  sell  and 
buy  farm  supplies  and  products,  while  others  leave  this  busi- 
ness to  cooperative  societies  operating  alongside  of  them 
and  organized  for  the  purpose  through  their  financial  assist- 
ance. No  farmer  can  become  a  member  of  a  bank  unless  he 
is  the  head  of  a  family.  He  may  not  withdraw  his  savings 
as  long  as  he  has  a  debt  unpaid  in  the  bank,  but  must  use 


^08  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

them  for  its  gradual  extinction.  The  maximum  maturity  for 
loans  is  two  years,  and  it  cannot  be  extended  except  in  case 
of  bad  crops,  when  a  renewal  of  only  six  months  is  permitted. 

A  central  bank  was  established  for  the  local  banks  in 
Servia  at  the  very  beginning  of  the  cooperative  movement. 
This  bank  is  a  joint-stock  company,  and  its  first  shares  were 
subscribed  by  the  Danube  Department,  seven  districts  thereof, 
133  communes,  and  about  500  individuals.  The  shares  of 
the  central  bank  are  $30  each,  and  may  be  paid  for  in  in- 
stalments. No  local  bank  may  hold  over  100  shares,  but 
within  this  limit  each  local  bank  is  bound  to  subscribe  to 
as  many  shares  as  the  amount  of  the  credit  opened  for  it  is  a 
multiple  of  $300.  The  state  advanced  $400,000  to  the  cen- 
tral bank  without  interest  but  takes  no  part  in  its  manage- 
ment. The  central  bank,  besides  acting  as  the  financial 
head  and  clearing  house  of  the  cooperative  societies,  buys 
and  sells  to  them  either  for  cash  or  on  credit,  seed,  fertilizer, 
farm  implements  and  machinery  for  resale  to  their  members. 
Four  per  cent  interest  is  allowed  on  shares  and  on  deposits. 
The  surplus  goes  into  the  reserve.  The  interest  on  money 
borrowed  by  adherents  of  the  central  bank  is  so  fixed  that 
the  individual  farmers  obtain  loans  from  their  local  banks 
at  4%  to  six  per  cent  per  annum. 

A  national  federation  called  the  General  Union,  with 
headquarters  at  Belgrade,  is  the  supreme  authority  within 
this  agricultural  cooperative  credit  system  of  Servia.  The 
central  bank,  the  local  banks  and  all  other  rural  cooperative 
societies  must  by  the  law  become  members  of  the  Union, 
which  is  charged  with  the  duty  of  auditing  their  accounts 
and  supervising  their  affairs.  It  is  also  the  chief  organ  of 
propaganda  and  guidance  of  cooperation  in  the  kingdom.  It 
is  supported  by  contributions  of  four  cents  a  month  per 
head  from  all  members  of  adhering  organizations. 

Servia  has  public  granaries  in  addition  to  this  coopera- 
tive credit  system.  They  were  originally  established  when  the 
country  was  under  Turkish  rule  for  receiving  grain  turned  in 
for  taxes.  They  are  now  used  for  storage  of  cereals  for 
supplying  farmers  vrith  food  and  seed  during  bad  times.    They 


EUSSIA    AND    THE   BALKAlN    STATES      409 

are  kept  filled  by  a  law  which  requires  farmers  to  pay  a 
small  portion  of  their  taxes  in  kind  each  year.  In  return 
for  this  the  farmers  are  entitled  to  supplies  in  the  event  of 
loss  of  crops  from  drought,  inundation,  hail  or  iire.  But  in 
place  of  giving  so  many  bushels  of  grain,  the  Government 
now  grants  a  loan  which  must  be  repaid  after  the  next 
harvest.  The  granaries  may  sell  their  stores  and  convert 
them  into  cash,  but  the  proceeds  must  be  deposited  in  the 
public  banks  if  not  invested  in  farm  loans.  Grain  is  usually 
the  security  demanded  for  these  loans,  and  the  granaries 
may  mingle  it  without  regard  from  whom  it  comes.  The 
granaries  are  managed  by  the  communes  in  which  they 
are  located,  subject  to  the  supervision  of  the  Minister  of 
Agriculture. 

The  organization  of  agricultural  credit  in  Bulgaria  began 
"with  a  law  enacted  by  the  Ottoman  Government  in  1865, 
which  was  based  on  a  project  formulated  several  years  pre- 
viously by  Midhat  Pasha  who  was  then  the  Governor,  under 
the  Turkish  dominion,  of  what  now  corresponds  to  the  north- 
ern portion  of  the  present  kingdom. 

This  law  compelled  the  farmers  to  join  banks  which 
were  created  for  them  in  the  principal  cities  of  each  dis- 
trict. The  banks  were  managed  by  two  Mohammedan  and 
two  Christian  cashiers,  and  the  presence  of  the  four  was 
necessary  for  the  validity  of  any  act.  Working  funds  were 
raised  by  a  tax  levied  on  the  farmers  themselves.  This  tax 
could  be  paid  in  farm  produce.  Indeed,  the  farmers  were  too 
poor  to  pay  in  any  other  way,  since  they  had  been  giving  30  to 
100  per  cent  interest  on  loans  and  were  in  the  clutches  of  usur- 
ers. When  a  bank  accumulated  $1,000  it  was  authorized  to  be- 
gin business.  No  dividends  were  declared.  The  profits  went  by 
one-third  to  works  of  public  utility  and  by  two-thirds  to  in- 
crease the  bank's  capital. 

The  banks  were  enjoined  also  to  receive  repayments  of 
their  loans  in  kind,  and  in  consequence  at  the  start  they 
resembled  country  stores  more  than  financial  institutions. 
However,  they  reduced  interest  rates  to  nine  or  ten  per  cent 


410  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

and  were  doing  esceillent  service  by  1877,  ■when  the  Turco- 
Eussian  war  broke  out  and  gave  them  a  bad  setback.  Most 
of  them  were  plundered  of  all  their  funds  and  records  by 
the  retreating  Turks,  and  borrowers  refused  to  pay  up  after 
this  destruction  of  the  evidence  of  their  debts.  The  loss 
was  recouped  by  the  issue  of  bonds. 

The  Eussian  Government  upon  coming  into  control  of 
the  country  proceeded  to  make  some  changes  in  these  banks, 
by  confining  them  exclusively  to  farmers,  placing  them  under 
the  direction  of-  the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  and  giving 
them  a  few  cooperative  features  by  allowing  members  of 
each  bank  to  elect  a  committee  of  nine  to  manage  it  in 
conjunction  with  a  cashier  and  comptroller  appointed  by  the 
Minister  of  Agriculture.  This  was  the  situation  of  the  banks 
when  Bulgaria  became  free.  The  independent  state,  always 
strongly  inclined  to  centralism  and  bureaucracy,  in  1894 
consolidated  all  existing  banks  and  utilized  their  funds  to 
form  one  big  central  bank  under  the  name  of  the  Central  Ag- 
ricultural Bank  of  Bulgaria,  which  now  has  85  branches  and 
75  agencies. 

The  consolidation  gave  the  Central  Agricultural  Bank  a 
capital  of  $8,000,000.  The  chief  object  of  this  institution  is 
to  assist  farmers,  but  it  may  grant  loans  to  any  other  per- 
sons up  to  the  amount  of  deposits  made  by  them.  It  pos- 
sesses the  usual  banking  powers  and  the  right  to  issue  deben- 
tures guaranteed  by  the  state.  Its  credit  is  accorded  to 
farmers  individually  and  to  rural  cooperative  societies,  and 
it  takes  as  security  mortgages  on  real  estate  or  growing  crops, 
live  stock  or  produce.  Short-term  loans  may  not  exceed 
$4,000,  nor  long-term  loans  of  two  to  20  years,  $20,000. 
Although  this  central  bank,  theoretically  at  least,  is  owned 
by  the  towns  and  villages  in  proportion  to  the  quotas  which 
their  respective  banks  contributed  towards  its  foundation, 
they  have  no  voice  in  its  administration.  It  is  managed  by 
a  president  and  four  directors  appointed  by  the  Crown.  No 
dividends  are  declared.  The  profits  are  disposed  of  as  fol- 
lows: 13  per  cent  is  set  aside  each  year  to  meet  possible 
losses;  three  per  cent  as  a  bonus  to  officials  and  employees; 


EUSSIA    AND    THE    BALKAN"    STATES      411' 

35  per  cent  for  the  reserve ;  35  per  cent  to  increase  the  work- 
ing funds;  and  25  per  cent  to  the  advancement  of  agri- 
culture. 

The  scope  of  the  Central  Agricultural  Bank  is  national, 
and  it  applies  its  resources  especially  to  develop  rural  coop- 
eration. To  this  end  it  requires  its  stafE  to  study  the  sub- 
ject of  cooperation,  while  it  gratuitously  instructs  school 
teachers  and  priests  in  the  elementary  principles  of  banking 
so  that  they  may  become  competent  organizers  and  managers 
of  rural  banks.  In  1910  its  capital  was  $8,569,080,  reserves 
$2,569,199,  and  deposits  and  accounts  $11,138,277.  Its  total 
business  was  $224,888,416,  of  which  $6,245,273  was  real- 
estate  mortgage  loans  made  ia  part  from  the  proceeds  of 
foreign  sales  of  its  debentures.  The  profits  were  $2,573,689. 
The  bank  is  exempted  from  taxes  and  has  the  free  use  of  the 
mails  and  public  telegraph. 

The  educational  work  and  financial  assistance  of  the 
Central  Agricultural  Bank  of  Bulgaria  has  given  a  rapid  de- 
velopment to  rural  credit  societies.  They  have  all  taken  a 
modified  EaifiEeisen  form.  The  first  was  started  by  Kardjew, 
an  instructor  in  an  agricultural  school  at  Eustchuk.  The 
success  of  this  society  induced  the  teachers  of  the  county 
schools  to  hold  a  convention  a  couple  of  years  later,  after 
which  the  movement  for  cooperation  began  in  earnest.  In 
1910  there  were  775  EaifEeisen  credit  societies  with  more 
than  40,000  members,  with  assets  whose  combined  value  ex- 
ceeded $28,282,870.  The  loans  for  the  year  amounted  to 
about  $3,000,000,  supplied  in  part  from  the  Central  Agricul- 
tural Bank.  The  societies  are  nearly  all  united  to  one  or  other 
of  two  federations,  which  are  supported  by  contributions  of  ad- 
herents and  subsidies  from  the  Department  of  Agriculture. 

Under  the  law  of  1907  these  federations  had  supervision 
over  rural  credit  societies  jointly  with  the  Central  Agricul- 
tural Bank.  This  troublesome  double  supervision,  however, 
no  longer  exists.  In  1910  the  Bidgarian  Government,  in  exe- 
cution of  a  plan  it  had  long  had  in  view,  created  a  new  central 
establishment,  and  gave  to  it  the  exclusive  right  of  super- 
vising the  societies,  made  it  their  financial  head,  and  en- 


412  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

trusted  it  with  the  duty  of  directing  and  developing  coop- 
eration for  all  its  varied  purposes  in  town  as  well  as  country 
throughout  the  kingdom. 

This  Central  Cooperative  Bank  is  a  public  institution,  and 
has  no  duplicate  in  any  other  nation.  The  capital  stock 
is  without  fixed  limit.  The  Central  Agricultural  Bank  and 
the  Ifational  Bank  were  forced  to  furnish  $1,000,000  on  which 
it  started  and  are  compelled  to  contribute  a  certain  portion 
of  their  annual  profits  to  the  increase  of  its  capital.  These 
two  institutions  are  called  foundation  members.  They  are  al- 
lowed dividends  of  four  per  cent,  but  must  serve  gratuitously 
as  correspondents  of  the  Central  Cooperative  Bank  and  act 
as  its  representatives  in  all  legal  business.  They  are  liable 
on  its  engagements  up  to  the  amount  of  their  contributions. 
Cooperative  associations  and  federations  must  subscribe  to 
one  share  of  $30  upon  joining.  They  are  called  ordinary 
members  and  to  them  alone  may  the  bank  extend  credit. 
Their  shares  may  be  paid  for  by  instalments.  The  shares 
draw  five  per  cent  dividends  and  carry  a  liability  up  to  five 
times  their  face  value.  No  other  concerns  or  individuals 
may  be  members. 

The  administration  of  this  Central  Cooperative  Bank 
consists  of  a  board  of  management,  a  superior  council,  an 
auditing  committee,  and  the  members  when  regularly  as- 
sembled. The  first  is  composed  of  one  manager  and  two 
regents.  They  have  the  character  of  public  functionaries, 
are  appointed  by  the  Crown,  and  can  be  removed  only  by 
Parliament.  The  second  is  composed  of  seven  members, 
two  appointed  by  the  National  Bank  and  Central  Agricul- 
tural Bank,  three  by  the  affiliated  societies,  one  by  the  Min- 
ister of  Commerce  and  Agriculture,  and  one  by  the  Min- 
ister of  Finance.  Their  term  of  office  is  one  year.  Their 
compensation  is  a  per  diem  allowance  for  attendance. 

The  auditing  committee  is  composed  of  five  members, 
one  appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Finance,  two  by  the  Na- 
tional Bank  and  Central  Agricultural  Bank,  and  two  by  the 
ordinary  members.  Their  term  is  three  years.  The  auditors 
act  as  field  inspectors,  guard  the  bank  against  irregular!- 


EUSSIA   AND    THE   BALKAN    STATES      413 

ties,  and  prepare  its  financial  statement  and  annual  ac- 
counts. The  meeting  of  the  members  must  be  held  once 
a  year,  but  they  can  vote  on  no  subject  except  the  election 
of  oflBcers.  The  supreme  control  is  lodged  with  the  Minister 
of  Agriculture,  who  may  veto  all  decisions  and  stop  any  opera- 
tion or  transaction  of  which  he  disapproves. 

The  Central  Cooperative  Bank  of  Bulgaria  may  issue 
debentures  redeemable  by  lot,  but  it  is  forbidden  to  make 
real-estate  loans  or  to  do  any  business  with  outsiders  except 
to  take  their  money  on  deposit.  It  is  authorized  to  own  and 
operate  warehouses  for  the  storage  of  farm  produce,  and  also 
to  give  financial  aid  to  mutual  societies  of  insurance  against 
haU  and  cattle  losses.  Ordinary  members  may  be  expelled 
but  cannot  retire  except  by  consent  obtained  at  a  meeting 
of  the  shareholders.  Since  1911,  when  it  began  business, 
the  Bank  has  been  exempted  from  stamp  duties  and  certain, 
other  taxes  and  has  enjoyed  the  free  use  of  the  postal  and  tele- 
graphic services. 

A  Eaiffeisen  cooperative  credit  society  was  opened  in 
European  Turkey  by  some  Servian  inhabitants  near  Con- 
stantinople in  April,  1907.  About  the  same  time  a  similar 
society  was  started  in  Montenegro.  Neither  was  successful, 
and  there  is  not  known  to  be  any  cooperative  credit  society 
of  any  sort  in  that  part  of  European  Turkey  now  within 
the  kingdom  of  Albania.  No  effort  to  start  a  cooperative 
credit  movement  has  been  made  in  Greece. 

In  Cjrprus  a  few  years  ago  there  were  22  credit  societies 
of  the  Eaiffeisen  type,  all  started  and  fostered  by  a  govern- 
ment ofBcial.  They  dissolved  when  this  ofBcial  changed  his 
post  and  left  nobody  to  direct  their  administration,  but 
during  their  short  existience  they  collected  in  the  district  of 
Paphos,  in  which  they  were  located,  more  savings  than 
were  collected  by  the  Public  Savings  Bank  in  the  entire  island 
within  five  years. 

The  cooperative  credit  movement  was  revived  in  Cyprus 
recently  by  the  Savings  Bank  of  Nicosia.  This  is  a  joint- 
stock  company  with  shares  of  $50  each.    The  majority  of  its 


414  EUKAL   CEBDITS 

2,000  shareholders  are  working  men  and  women,  mostly 
servants  and  weavers.  In  December,  1909,  Mr.  Economides, 
the  president  of  this  bank,  and  William  Bevan  of  the  Agri- 
cultural Department  of  the  island  fonnded  a  new  credit  so- 
ciety in  the  village  of  Lefkonico.  It  is  of  the  EaifEeisen  type 
but  exacts  an  entrance  fee  of  about  50  cents  from  each 
member.  This  has  been  followed  by  a  few  other  societies, 
aU  financially  supported  and  supervised  by  the  Bank.  They 
pay  interest  at  the  rate  of  eight  per  cent  for  deposits  and 
charge  borrowers  ten  per  cent. 

Cooperative  credit  is  practised  in  the  Jewish  farm  col- 
onies in  Palestine.  The  first  of  these  colonies,  composed  of 
refugees  from  Eussia  and  followers  of  the  Zionist  movement, 
was  founded  in  1882  on  a  tract  of  land  six  miles  south  of 
Jaffa  on  the  road  to  Gaza.  Its  success  led  to  the  formation 
of  other  colonies,  all  of  which  Baron  de  Eothschild  put  under 
his  protection.  He  named  one  colony  Zichron-Jaeob  after 
his  father,  and  another  Mazkeret-Bathyra  after  his  mother. 
He  planted  the  eucalyptus  to  keep  off  the  malaria,  induced 
the  colonists  to  dig  wine  cellars  and  grow  vines  and  fruit 
trees,  and  spent  many  hundreds  of  thousands  of  dollars  in 
these  philanthropic  ventures  for  his  coreligionists. 

There  are  now  about  9,500  Jewish  immigrant  farmers 
with  their  descendants  in  Palestine.  They  make  wine,  cognac 
and  attar  of  roses,  and  raise  olives,  almonds,  oranges  and 
figs,  some  wheat,  barley,  cotton  and  other  staple  agricul- 
tural products.  The  colonists  apply  cooperation  in  the  manu- 
facture and  marketing  of  their  commodities,  and  through 
the  associations  which  they  have  formed  for  these  purposes 
frequently  extend  credit  to  members. 


CHAPTER   XXIX 

SPAIN   AKD    POETTTGAIi 

PositoB. — ^Need  of  Credit. — Operation  of  Positos. — ^Recent  Credit 
Societies. — The  Leo  XIII,  the  Bank  of  Spain  and  the  Mortgage 
Bank. — Government  Help  for  Cooperative  Societies. — ^Misericor- 
dias  and  CeUeiros  Communs  of  Portugal. — Modem  Agricul- 
tural Mutual  Credit  System. — ^Agricultural  Credit  Board  and 
Bank  of  Portugal. — ^Republics  of  Andorra  and  San  Marino. — 
Monaco  and  Liechtenstein. 

CooPEEATiVE  credit  is  gaining  a  foothold  in  Spain,  but 
the  ancient  positos  are  still  the  leading  institutions  for  ex- 
tending financial  aid  to  the  Spanish  farmers.  The  positos 
are  public  granaries.  The  oldest  date  back  to  the  fifteenth 
century.  They  were  all  established  by  the  Government  or  by 
private  beneficence  for  the  same  purpose  which  prompted 
Pharaoh  to  store  up  corn  during  the  seven  fat  years  for  use 
during  the  ensuing  famine. 

Spain  has  been  in  continual  decline  since  the  close  of  the 
Middle  Ages.  The  decline  was  stayed  for  a  time  by  the 
gold  plundered  from  newly  discovered  countries  in  Central 
and  South  America,  but  when  this  source  of  revenue  was 
taken  away,  the  downward  trend  was  resumed  and  Spain 
lost  by  degrees  her  former  strength  and  glory.  Today  her 
population  is  barely  more  than  one-half  of  what  it  was  in 
the  days  of  the  Caesars.  This  decadence  is  due  in  large 
measure  to  the  fact  that  vast  areas  of  her  lands  have  been 
worn  out  by  generations  of  unscientific  farming  or  swept 
barren  by  torrents  pouring  down  from  mountain  ranges  long 
since  deprived  of  their  forests.  At  present  Spain  is  in  great 
want  of  money  both  for  the  short  term  needed  for  agri- 
cultural industries  and  for  the  long  term  required  for  re- 

415 


416  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

claiming  the  upper  valleys  by  irrigation  and  the  marshy 
coastal  regions  by  drainage  and  embankments  and  for  ena- 
bling the  farmers  to  acquire  title  to  the  land  they  cultivate. 

An  effort  was  made  in  1873  to  create  credit  facilities  for 
the  latter  objects  by  establishing  a  mortgage  bank  with  an 
exclusive  monopoly  of  issuing  debentures,  under  a  president 
appointed  by  the  Crown.  It  has  not  done  much  good.  Its 
outstanding  loans  at  the  beginning  of  1912  amounted  to 
$30,757,604,  a  relatively  unimportant  figure  in  view  of  its 
privileges  and  opportimities  and  quite  insignificant  when 
compared  with  what  ought  to  be  accomplished.  The  larger 
proportion  of  these  loans  was  on  urban  properties,  and  the 
average  size  of  loans  was  $6,880,  showing  that  nothiag  had 
been  done  except  for  the  large  or  medium-sized  estates.  After 
the  establishment  of  this  mortgage  bank  several  institutions 
were  founded  for  lending  small  sums  for  short  terms,  and 
although  they  have  met  with  better  success,  the  positos  yet 
continue  to  be  the  main  stand-by  of  the  small  farmers,  just 
as  they  were  often  their  last  resource  in  the  near  as  well  as 
the  distant  past  when  the  effects  of  denudation  and  exhaustion 
of  the  soil  and  improvident  farming  and  living  began  to 
manifest  themselves. 

Originally  the  practice  was  to  fill  the  positos  or  granaries 
with  the  surplus  of  good  years  to  be  doled  out  during  dearths 
and  thus  steady  prices  and  tide  over  the  needy  to  the  nest 
crop.  But  the  grain  had  to  be  changed  at  intervals  to  pre- 
vent its  spoiling,  and  this  led  to  the  adoption  of  the  idea 
of  the  Portuguese  celleiros,  of  lending  seed  to  farmers  to  be 
returned  with  a  bonus  at  the  end  of  the  harvest,  and  finally 
of  selling  whatever  surplus  of  grain  might  be  on  hand  and 
making  cash  loans  with  the  proceeds.  The  constitution  and 
method  of  management  of  the  positos  have  undergone  vari- 
ous changes  in  the  course  of  time.  At  present  they  are  sub- 
ject to  the  control  of  the  Minister  of  Agriculture,  exercised 
through  a  commissioner  appointed  for  five  years  by  the 
Crown. 

Eecently  the  immovable  property  of  the  positos  has  been 
ordered  sold  or  converted  into  liquid  assets,  while  their  pow- 


SPAIN   AND   POETUGAL  417 

ers  and  objects  have  been  enlarged  so  as  to  include  the  re- 
ceiving of  deposits,  the  purchase  of  live  stock  and  agricul- 
tural machines  for  sale  or  hire,  and  the  granting  of  loans 
ia  cash  for  terms  adjusted  to  the  necessities  or  convenience 
of  the  farmers.  In  fact  the  positos  have  been  so  modernized 
by  law  during  the  last  few  years  that  they  have  become  rural 
banks,  and  the  Government  is  actively  engaged  in  transform- 
ing them  into  banks  and  increasing  their  number.  But  they 
are  still  managed  as  of  old  by  the  communal  councils,  to 
■which  is  awarded  one-sixth  of  one  per  cent  of  the  interest  on 
the  loans  as  compensation  for  the  personal  liability  imposed 
upon  them  for  granting  the  loans. 

New  positos  may  be  created  by  the  public  authorities  upon 
proof  of  the  need  for  them,  of  the  sufficiency  of  their  endow- 
ment or  capital,  and  of  their  ability  to  carry  out  the  under- 
takings laid  down  in  the  plans  of  their  scope  of  action  sub- 
mitted. Borrowers  have  no  voice  in  the  creation  of  the 
positos  nor  in  the  conduct  of  their  afEairs,  so  these  institu- 
tions have  no  cooperative  features.  There  were  3,529  positos 
in  Spain  at  the  beginning  of  1913,  with  outstanding  loans 
amounting  to  $15,394,968  and  total  assets  of  $19,085,980. 
The  size  of  the  average  loan  was  $G4  and  the  interest  rate 
six  per  cent  a  year,  which  indicates  that  they  have  become 
important  factors  in  small  credit. 

The  introduction  of  cooperative  credit  in  Spain  occurred 
with  the  opening  of  a  Eaiffeisen  bank  on  June  30,  1901, 
at  Amusco,  in  the  province  of  Valencia,  by  the  abbot  Valentin 
Gomez,  whose  enthusiasm  for  rural  cooperative  credit  was 
aroused  to  action  by  a  resolution  passed  in  its  favor  at  a 
Catholic  convention  held  in  1899.  The  prebend  Anacleto 
Orejon  founded  a  similar  bank  in  the  same  province  on  March 
30,  1902.  Shortly  afterwards  Louis  Chaves  founded  four 
others  in  the  province  of  Zamora.  Then  came  the  law  of 
1906  on  agricultural  associations  and  the  law  of  1908  exempt- 
ing such  associations  which  had  credit  for  their  objects  or 
one  of  their  objects  from  certain  taxes.  An  energetic  move- 
ment followed,  which  assumed  the  syndical  character  of  the 
French  cooperative  credit  system,  but  was  impelled  in  the 


418  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

main  by  the  Catholic  church.  At  the  beginning  of  1913  there 
were  127  pure  Catholic  rural  cooperative  credit  societies, 
and  1,154  syndicais.  Catholic  and  undenomiaational  com- 
bined, of  which  638  were  banks  or  had  credit  for  one  of 
their  objects. 

The  credit  societies  in  the  province  of  Zamora  impose 
unlimited  liability.  Members  make  no  contributions  of  any 
kind  except  deposits.  The  working  funds  are  obtained  from 
donations  or  borrowed  money.  The  only  paid  officer  or  em- 
ployee is  the  cashier  or  accountant.  The  cooperative  credit 
societies  in  some  of  the  other  provinces  have  a  capital  com- 
posed of  public  subventions  and  membership  shares  of  $2, 
each  payable  in  monthly  instalments  of  five  cents. 

Many  of  the  credit  societies  besides  doing  a  loan  and 
savings  business  supply  their  members  on  credit  with  seed, 
fertilizer  and  other  requirements  for  agricultural  work  and 
the  raising  of  live  stock,  and  furthermore  take  produce  in 
storage  for  safekeeping  or  collective  selling.  Members  must 
furnish  lists  of  all  property  owned  by  them  and  their  wives. 
Their  standing  is  determined  and  the  maximum  fixed  for 
their  credit  by  these  lists.  Security  is  always  required  for 
the  loans.  Deposits  as  low  as  a  penny  at  a  time  are  received, 
but  they  do  not  draw  interest  unless  profitable  use  can  be 
found  for  them. 

Cooperative  credit  societies  are  not  yet  sufficiently  num- 
erous in  Spain  for  the  organization  of  a  federation  or  a 
central  institution  by  and  for  themselves.  But  there  exists 
the  Leo  XIII,  a  bank  of  a  religious  character  founded  by 
the  Archbishop  of  Zaragoza  for  the  sole  purpose  of  assist- 
ing the  agricultural  and  industrial  classes,  which  makes  ad- 
vances either  in  loans  or  discounts  to  the  rural  credit  so- 
cieties at  four  and  five  per  cent  and  gives  three  per  cent  on 
their  deposits.  The  Bank  of  Spain  and  the  Mortgage  Bank 
also  accommodate  the  rural  credit  societies  but  to  a  less  extent 
and  at  somewhat  higher  interest  than  the  Leo  XIII.  The 
facilities  accorded  by  these  three  large  banks,  however,  are 
fax  from  sufficient,  and  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  has 
presented  a  bill  to  the  Cortes  for  the  establishment  of  the 


SPAIN  AND  POETUGAL  419 

National  Agricultural  Credit  Institute.  This  bank,  if 
formed,  will  be  placed  under  the  control  of  the  Government 
and  endowed  with  a  capital  of  $200,000  and  a  working  fund 
of  $10,000,000  raised  by  bond  issues.  The  proposed  bank 
will  audit  and  supervise  the  positos  and  rural  credit  societies, 
make  loans  at  four  per  cent,  and  carry  on  propaganda  for  the 
diffusion  of  cooperative  credit.  Another  project  also  has 
been  presented  to  the  Cortes  for  a  private  agricultural  bank 
with  a  capital  stock  of  $30,000,000. 

The  law  of  1906  was  the  first  of  its  kind  enacted  in  Spain. 
It  allows  associations  and  combiaations  of  associations  to 
be  formed  for  all  agricultural  purposes,  specifies  their  rights 
and  obKgations,  and  lays  down  rules  for  their  organization 
and  management.  It  enumerates  the  various  tax  exemptions 
which  they  may  enjoy,  and  provides  state  aid  to  encourage 
their  development  along  certain  lines. 

The  Spanish  Government  has  itself  started  a  number  of 
cooperative  societies  in  carrying  out  its  policy  and  plans  of 
settling  xmemployed  families  in  the  places  where  they  were 
born  so  as  to  check  emigration  and  repeople  the  country 
districts.  These  families  are  required  to  form  themselves 
into  cooperative  societies  before  they  may  receive  the  sub- 
ventions which  the  state  has  appropriated  for  this  home  col- 
onization. These  subventions  may  be  used  for  the  purchase 
of  farm  equipment  and  even  for  buying  food  and  clothing 
to  keep  the  families  alive  until  crops  are  harvested,  but  only 
on  condition  that  they  render  themselves  jointly  and  sever- 
ally liable  to  the  state  through  cooperation  for  the  money 
advanced  to  any  one  of  them. 

In  Portugal  there  is  now  a  national  agricultural  coop- 
erative credit  system  aided  by  the  state  and  evolved  along  the 
lines  of  French  syndicalism.  But  imtil  this  system  came 
into  existence  the  Portuguese  farmers  had  no  place  to  go 
for  cheap  and  easy  loans  except  the  misericordias  and  celleiros 
communs,  whose  funds  were  far  from  being  sufficient  for  their 
purpose. 

The  misericordias  are  benevolent  institutions  whose  ob- 


420  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

jeet  is  to  succor  the  poor,  the  sick  and  prisoners  worthy  of 
help  but  too  proud  to  beg.  Their  capital  is  composed  of 
contributions  of  members,  usually  rich  or  well-to-do,  and  do- 
nations and  legacies.  The  first  was  founded  by  Queen 
Donna  Eleonora  at  Lisbon  in  1498,  and  its  charitable  ob- 
jects included  the  building  of  hospitals,  the  care  of  orphans, 
the  freeing  of  slaves,  and  the  giving  of  dowries  to  young 
women  in  order  to  enable  them  to  marry.  As  numerous 
other  misericordias  were  formed  and  as  their  funds  in- 
creased, authority  was  granted  them  to  make  loans  on  mort- 
gage to  clear  lands  and  also  to  establish  credit  banks  to 
make  loans  for  agriexdtural  purposes.  They  were  authorized 
also,  however,  to  make  loans  to  industry  and  commerce,  and 
these  being  more  profitable,  they  eventually  ignored  agri- 
culture. At  present  there  are  149  misericordias,  and  their 
combined  capital  is  only  about  $3,053,383. 

The  celleiros  communs  are  similar  to  the  Spanish  positos 
and  the  Italian  monti  frumentarii.  The  first  celleiros  was 
founded  by  King  Sebastian  in  1576  with  the  object  of  pro- 
viding farmers  with  seed  during  the  dearth  of  that  year. 
A  few  more  were  founded  by  royal  munificence  and  others 
by  municipalities,  parishes  and  private  individuals.  Their 
source  of  revenue  was  the  income  from  donations  and  lega- 
cies and  later  on  from  taxes  and  compulsory  contributions  of 
grain  from  peasants.  Originally  the  celleiros  were  man- 
aged according  to  the  decision  of  their  founders  and  were 
subject  to  their  unrestricted  control,  but  in  1852  they  were 
all  reorganized  by  law,  converted  into  rural  banks  and  placed 
imder  the  management  of  local  public  authorities.  They 
were  authorized  to  erect  warehouses  and  grain  elevators  and 
to  do  a  warehouse  business,  and  they  were  granted  tas  ex- 
emptions and  special  privileges  with  the  view  of  encouraging 
them  to  aid  agriculture.  But  they  were  not  successful,  and 
their  number  gradually  declined  until  in  1911  there  re- 
mained only  14,  with  $128,288  of  combined  capital,  of  the  52 
celleiros  which  existed  in  1852. 

These  ancient  institutions  were  completely  eliminated 
from  agriculture  in  1911  when  a  law  was  enacted  for  the 


SPAIN  AND  POETUGAL  421 

establishment  of  an  agricultural  mutual  credit  system.  This 
law  decreed  the  abolishment  of  the  celleiros,  ordered  their 
funds  to  be  turned  over  to  the  system,  and  furthermore  ar- 
ranged to  give  so  much  assistance  to  the  new  agricultural 
banks  that  there  is  now  neither  use  nor  opportunity  for  any 
other  kind.  The  present  head  of  this  system  is  the  Agri- 
cultural Credit  Board,  a  bureau  in  the  Department  of  Agri- 
culture, composed  of  four  members  appointed  by  the  Gov- 
ernment and  three  others  elected  by  the  mutual  banks  and 
approved  by  the  Government.  This  Board  is  a  temporary 
body  which  will  be  dissolved  as  soon  as  the  system  grows 
large  enough  to  establish  a  central  bank  to  supersede  it.  But 
for  the  time  beiag  the  Board  has  entire  control  over  the 
system,  has  been  assigned  the  duty  of  fostering  its  develop- 
ment, and  is  entrusted  with  the  audit  and  supervision  of  the 
banks  and  with  the  distribution  of  the  subsidies  granted  for 
their  support. 

The  subsidies  for  this  system  come  through  the  Bank  of 
Portugal.  The  Government  requires  this  bank  of  issue  to 
open  an  account  at  its  headquarters  and  branches  in  favor 
of  the  Agricultural  Credit  Board.  The  account  is  guaran- 
teed by  the  state  and  its  extent  is  determined  by  contracts 
executed  by  virtue  of  law  between  the  Government  and  the 
Bank.  The  amount  was  put  at  $1,500,000  the  first  year. 
The  business  transacted  by  the  Bank  of  Portugal  with  the 
Board  and  the  agricultural  mutual  credit  banks  is  done 
without  charge  or  profit,  the  sole  compensation  being  one- 
fourth  of  one  per  cent  on  the  total  amount  of  the  current 
account  in  each  bank  as  shown  by  weekly  settlements.  The 
transfer  of  funds  from  the  cities  in  which  the  branches  of 
the  Bank  of  Portugal  are  located  to  the  places  where  the 
agricultural  mutual  credit  banks  are  situated  is  made  through 
the  postofBce  by  registered  mail,  the  agricultural  mutual 
credit  banks  giving  duplicate  receipts  indicating  the  sum  re- 
ceived, which  are  handed  to  the  postman.  Payments  may  be 
remitted  in  the  same  way. 

This  Portuguese  agricultural  mutual  credit  system  can- 
not distribute  the  subsidies  obtained  from  the  state  to  any  and 


423  ETJEAL    CEEDITS 

all  classes  of  farmers.  The  law  distinctly  states  that  the 
only  banks  which  may  belong  to  the  system  are  those  formed 
by  members  of  agricxdtural  syndicats  or  of  agricultural  pro- 
fessional associations.  The  law  defines  such  an  association  to 
be  one  composed  only  of  farmers  or  of  farmers  and  other 
persons  exercising  industries  or  callings  allied  to  agricul- 
ture. Thus  in  order  to  become  a  member  and  borrower  of 
an  agricultural  mutual  credit  bank,  the  Portuguese  farmer 
must  prove  not  only  that  he  is  actually  and  directly  culti- 
vating the  soil  but  also  that  he  belongs  to  an  agricultural 
association  in  the  locality.  Furthermore,  the  business  of  this 
syndicat  or  association  must  be  confined  to  one  or  more  of 
the  following  objects:  the  purchase  of  seed,  plants,  insecti- 
cides, fertilizer  and  things  for  improving  the  soil;  cattle, 
feed,  implements  and  machinery  and  means  of  transporta- 
tion; the  payment  of  wages,  rent,  and  working  expenses;  or 
the  execution  of  work  to  improve  the  value  of  the  soil  or 
property.  Such  an  association  may  itself  be  a  member  of 
the  bank. 

The  members  of  an  agricultural  mutual  credit  bank, 
therefore,  may  be  individual  organized  farmers  and  asso- 
ciations of  farmers.  The  chief  object  of  the  bank  is  to  accord 
credit  to  its  members,  but  only  for  the  production,  manu- 
facture, marketing  and  sale  of  farm  produce;  or  for  the  pur- 
chase, upkeep,  or  installation  of  warehouses  and  workshops 
for  agricultural  machinery  and  material  and  vehicles  for 
hauling;  or  for  the  acquisition  of  agricultural  machines. 

For  the  purpose  of  raising  funds  for  carrying  on  its  op- 
erations an  agricultural  mutual  credit  bank  may  receive,  be- 
sides the  subsidies  from  the  state,  moneys  by  donation  or 
legacies  or  on  deposit  from  members  or  any  other  persons. 
The  interest  rate  on  deposits  must  never  exceed  four  per 
cent,  and  the  rate  on  money  borrowed  by  the  bank  must  not 
exceed  that  actually  given  on  the  deposits. 

The  sphere  of  operations  of  each  local  bank  is  one  com- 
mune. Local  banks  may  unite  to  form  district  banks,  with 
the  consent  of  the  Minister  of  Agriculture  obtained  through 
the  Agricultural  Credit  Board.     The  articles  of  agreement 


SPAIN   AND   PORTUGAL  423 

of  a  local  bank,  drafted  on  a  model  prepared  by  this  Board 
and  duly  sworn  to  and  filed  as  a  public  document,  must  be 
signed  by  at  least  ten  farmers,  and  specify  the  conditions  for 
the  admission  and  expulsion  of  members,  define  their  rights, 
obligations  and  liabilities,  prescribe  the  method  of  organizing 
the  committee  of  management  and  the  meetings  of  members, 
and  define  their  respective  duties  and  powers. 

The  liability  of  members  may  be  limited  to  a  share  or  to 
an  amount  of  which  the  share  is  a  multiple,  or  it  may  be 
unlimited  and  render  members  jointly  and  severally  liable 
for  all  debts  of  the  bank.  But  creditors  cannot  touch  the 
members  until  legal  remedies  against  the  bank  have  been 
exhausted.  A  limited-liability  bank  may  issue  shares  and 
pay  dividends  up  to  4%  per  cent  a  year.  Indeed,  one-half 
of  the  profits  must  be  annually  applied  to  paying  back  the 
shares  of  members.  But  ia  an  unlimited-liability  bank, 
neither  the  profits  nor  any  of  the  funds  coming  from  sub- 
scriptions, entrance  fees,  gifts,  subsidies  or  from  any  other 
source  may  be  distributed  among  members.  All  the  profits 
are  put  into  the  reserve,  and  in  the  event  of  dissolution 
this  fimd  must  be  turned  over  to  the  Agricultural  Credit 
Board  to  be  used  in  founding  a  new  bank  in  the  same  com- 
mune, or  in  some  undertaking  therein  of  an  agricultural  na- 
ture if  a  new  bank  is  not  formed  within  one  year.  The 
only  officers  who  may  receive  pay  are  the  treasurer  and  the 
accountant. 

The  loans  of  a  bank  must  not  be  for  longer  than  one 
year,  with  a  renewal  for  one  year  more.  The  maximum 
interest  is  five  per  cent,  except  for  loans  made  from  funds  of 
the  celleiroSj  on  which  it  is  three  per  cent.  Pledges,  deposits, 
assignments  of  income,  signature  of  sureties  or  mortgages 
are  always  required  for  security.  In  loans  secured  by  in- 
dorsement, the  surety  is  considered  to  be  primarily  liable. 
Loans  on  real  estate  must  be  secured  by  first  mortgages. 
None  can  be  over  $1,000,  and  the  total  must  not  exceed  one- 
fifth  of  the  outstanding  loans  of  the  bank.  No  member  may 
borrow  a  sum  of  more  than  50  per  cent  of  the  value  of  the 
security  offered  plus  25  per  cent  of  the  value  of  unencumbered 


424  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

real  estate  owned  by  him  or  his  sureties.  The  purpose  of  the 
loan  must  be  stated  in  the  application,  and  if  the  borrower 
uses  it  in  any  other  way,  he  must  be  expelled  and  can  never 
become  a  member  of  another  agricultural  mutual  credit  bank, 
besides  being  liable  to  criminal  prosecution  and  a  fine  of  $5 
to  $500.  Preference  must  be  given  to  loans  for  small 
amounts.  An  appeal  lies  from  the  bank  to  the  Agricul- 
tural Credit  Board  in  cases  of  expulsion  or  refusal  of  ad- 
mittance or  of  an  application  for  a  loan. 

The  agricultural  mutual  credit  banks  may  use  their  re- 
serves as  well  as  their  other  funds  in  making  loans,  and  when 
their  funds  are  larger  than  are  necessary  for  the  needs  of 
their  members,  they  may  lend  the  excess  to  other  banks  of 
the  system  or  employ  it  in  local  agricultural  undertakings 
or  even  in  propaganda  for  diffusing  knowledge  of  coopera- 
tive credit.  The  banks,  the  business  done  by  them,  and 
their  paper  and  documents  are  exempt  from  all  taxes  and 
duties  and  their  correspondence  may  be  franked  through 
the  mails. 

But  the  moneys  advanced  to  a  bank  through  the  Agri- 
cultural Credit  Board  may  be  used  only  for  loans  to  mem- 
bers. The  advances  granted  by  the  Board  to  a  bank  or- 
ganized on  the  limited-liability  plan  must  not  exceed  twice 
its  capital.  The  advances  to  an  unlimited-liability  bank  are 
restricted  to  the  amount  of  the  capital  plus  50  per  cent  of  the 
combined  value  of  the  unencumbered  real  estate  owned  by 
members.  This  value  is  computed  by  taking  15  times  the 
taxable  revenues  as  assessed  for  taxes.  These  advances  run 
for  one  year  and  must  bear  at  least  3%  per  cent  per  annum. 
They  may  be  renewed,  but  with  an  increase  in  the  interest 
rate  which  may  be  one  per  cent  more. 

The  interest  is  collected  by  the  Bank  of  Portugal,  which 
must  render  a  weekly  account  thereof  to  the  Agricultural 
Credit  Board.  After  taking  out  the  one-fourth  of  one  t)er 
cent  allowed  it  for  expenses,  the  Bank  of  Portugal  must 
set  aside  the  balance  of  the  profits  coming  from  these  advances 
for  creating  a  fund  of  $200,000  to  be  used  for  agricultural 
operations.     This  fund  is  intended  also  to  cover  losses  sus- 


SPAIN  AND  PORTUGAL  425 

tained  by  the  Board  in  transactions  with  the  agricultural 
mutual  credit  banks,  and  may  be  used  by  the  Government  in 
any  way  it  deems  fit  for  encouragiag  agriculture  and  co- 
operation. 

The  communal  agricultural  mutual  credit  banks  may  open 
branches  and  agencies.  They  may  also  unite  to  form  district 
banks  and  these  in  turn  may  federate  to  form  a  central 
bank.  The  Agricultural  Credit  Board  ceases  to  do  business 
directly  with  a  local  bank  when  a  district  bank  has  been  or- 
ganized for  it.  The  district  banks  are  organized  exactly 
like  the  communal  or  local  banks.  In  case  of  dissolution  of 
an  unlimited-liability  district  bank,  its  assets,  if  any,  are 
turned  over  to  the  Agricultural  Credit  Board  to  be  distrib- 
uted among  adhering  local  banks.  The  same  distribution  is 
made  of  the  assets  of  a  limited-liability  district  bank  after 
paying  off  the  share  capital. 

The  central  bank  cannot  be  organized  until  each  dis- 
trict has  a  district  bank.  It  will  be  named  the  Central 
Bank  of  Agricultural  Credit,  with  headquarters  at  Lisbon. 
Its  plan  of  organization  and  administration  will  be  deter- 
mined by  the  Agricultural  Credit  Board,  and  when  it  be- 
gins operations  the  Board  will  turn  over  to  it  the  agricultural 
fund  which  is  accumulating  from  the  profits  derived  from 
the  advances  to  the  commimal  and  district  banks.  It  will 
then  dissolve  and  leave  the  management  of  the  system  in 
charge  of  the  Central  Bank,  which  will  replace  also  the 
Bank  of  Portugal. 

Very  slow  progress  has  been  made  in  developing  this  na- 
tional agricultural  credit  system  under  the  1911  law.  Po- 
litical disturbances  and  the  iudifference  and  distrust  of  the 
farmers  have  caused  much  interference  and  delay.  Obstacles 
have  arisen  also  because  of  the  restrictions  imposed  by  the 
law  on  loans  made  by  the  Agricultural  Credit  Board  to  un- 
limited-liability banks.  Very  few  individual  farmers  have 
unencumbered  real  estate.  Many  of  them  farm  land  held 
on  long  leases.  These  cannot  be  counted  in  estimating  the 
credit  standing  of  a  bank,  and  as  a  consequence  in  most 
localities  such  banks,  which  are  the  preferred  kind,  could 


426  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

not  obtain  sufficient  funds  for  their  operations.  Amend- 
ments have  been  presented  to  remove  these  objections  to  the 
law. 

In  1913  there  were  only  29  agricultural  mutual  credit 
banks  with  1,015  members,  a  very  insignificant  niunber  in 
view  of  the  fact  that  65  per  cent  of  the  5,016,267  of  the  pop- 
ulation of  Portugal  is  agricultural.  jB.owever,  the  $1,500,000 
placed  by  the  Government  at  the  disposal  of  the  banks  through 
the  Agricultural  Credit  Board  has  lowered  the  interest  rate 
to  their  members  from  20  per  cent  to  five  per  cent. 

The  Eepublic  of  Andorra  is  under  the  protection  of 
France  and  the  Archbishop  of  Urgel.  Its  farmers,  not  being 
citizens  of  France,  are  not  eligible  to  membership  ia  the 
banks  of  the  Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  but  the  nearby  banks 
of  the  French  Federation  of  the  Farmers'  and  Workmen's 
Banks  with  Unlimited  Liability  are  available  for  them.  The 
Eepublic  of  San  Marino  is  enclaved  in  Italy,  and  its  farm- 
ers have  access  to  the  Italian  Catholic  and  non-sectarian  rural 
credit  societies.  There  is  no  rural  cooperative  credit  society 
in  the  independent  principality  of  Monaco,  nor  have  any 
official  statistics  been  published  relating  to  cooperative  credit 
in  the  independent  principality  of  Liechtenstein. 


CHAPTBE  XXX 

BEITISH    INDIA,    JAPAN,     EGYPT,    AND     THE    APEICAN 
COLONIES 

Conditions  in  India. — The  Kuttuehuttu  and  Nidhis. — ^Work  of  Nichol- 
son and  WolfE. — Cooperative  Credit  Laws  of  1904  and  1912. — 
Development  of  Societies. — Statistics. — Early  Mutual  Aid  So- 
cieties in  Japan. — ^Law  of  1909. — Central  Association  of  Co- 
operative Societies. — Attempts  in  Egypt. — Society  of  Omar 
Lufty  Bey. — Credit  System  in  Algeria  and  Tunis. — Provident 
Societies. — Thrift  Societies  of  French  West  Africa. — Credit  So- 
cieties in  Java,  Windhoek. 

Within  an  area  one-third  as  great,  British  India  has  a 
population  nearly  three  times  as  large  as  that  of  the  United 
States.  The  land  yields  a  tropical  abundance,  but  is  afflicted 
by  frequent  droughts  and  plagues  which  cause  the  death  rate 
to  exceed  the  birth  rate  by  nearly  one-half  of  one  per  cent. 
The  250,000,000  of  inhabitants,  comprising  numerous  races 
of  varying  degrees  of  civilization  and  speaking  many  lan- 
guages, are  huddled  together  with  more  than  166  souls  to  the 
square  mile  and  are  so  ignorant  that  only  five  per  cent  of 
them  can  read  and  write.  The  vast  majority  suffer  from 
periodical  famines  and  live  in  such  pitiable  indigence  that 
their  sole  ambition  is  simply  to  keep  from  dying  of  hunger. 
And  yet  this  immense  empire  of  illiterate  and  poverty- 
stricken  people  is  supposed  to  have  more  gold,  gems  and 
jewels  than  any  other  nation. 

From  the  days  when  men  first  began  to  quarry  and  mine, 
the  Hindustani  have  been  collectors  of  precious  metals  and 
stones,  for  ornamental  display  by  their  rulers  or  superiors  and 
for  concealment  in  the  ground  or  secret  vaults  for  reasons 
whereof  no  satisfactory  explanation  has  ever  been  given.  The 
amount  of  gold  bullion  and  coin  thus  buried  and  hoarded  is 

427 


428  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

incaleulable.  British  India  now  imports  an  annual  average 
of  $60,000,000  of  gold  from  Europe,  South  Africa  and 
America.  Lord  Curzon  estimates  that  $2,750,000,000  has 
been  brought  in  since  England  assumed  imperial  dominion, 
to  say  nothing  of  what  has  come  in  by  way  of  China  and 
the  Orient,  and  has  vanished  from  circulation,  to  the  sacrifice 
of  at  least  $110,000,000  of  interest  a  year. 

This  absorption  and  disappearance  of  wealth  are  known 
to  have  been  going  on  to  swell  the  volume  of  hoarded  treas- 
ures of  previous  centuries.  The  efforts  being  made  to  stop  the 
practice  of  hoarding  meet  serious  opposition  because  of 
the  fact  that  perhaps  most  of  the  owners  and  hoarders  are 
Mussulmans,  who,  obeying  the  injunctions  of  the  Koran,  re- 
fuse to  take  interest  and  cannot  be  induced  to  put  their  money 
to  material  use.  Thus  it  happens  that  in  India,  rich  enough 
to  finance  all  its  people,  there  exist  side  by  side  magnificent 
opulence  and  abject  penury,  between  which  multitudes 
who  are  struggling  to  make  a  decent  living  are  unable  to 
obtain  the  necessary  capital  except  at  exorbitant  interest 
rates. 

An  indigenous  form  of  cooperative  society  for  thrift  and 
mutual  credit  has  existed  in  British  India  for  many  ages. 
This  is  the  Kuttuchuttu,  in  which  a  number  of  persons,  usu- 
ally of  the  same  village,  subscribe  a  fixed  weekly  or  monthly 
sum.  The  accumulated  amount  is  lent  successively  to  each 
member,  the  individual  selected  being  determined  by  lot  at 
regular  intervals,  all  former  winners  being  excluded  from 
the  drawings  but  being  required  to  continue  payments  on 
their  subscriptions.  Nidhis,  or  loan-fund  societies,  also 
sprang  up  about  the  middle  of  the  last  century.  These  are 
exactly  like  the  American  savings  and  loan  associations,  with 
the  exception  that  the  funds  are  not  necessarily  used  for 
building  purposes.  Mutual  or  collective  liability  likewise 
was  sometimes  required  by  the  Government  as  early  as  1883 
for  advances  made  by  the  state  in  hard  times  for  the  pur- 
chase of  seed  and  cattle  for  the  needy.  By  a  law  enacted  in 
that  year  all  the  inhabitants  of  a  village  receiving  such  an 
advance  could  be  made  personally  responsible  for  its  return. 


BRITISH  INDIA,  JAPAN,  EGYPT,  ETC.     439 

But  the  pure  European  form  of  eooperative  credit  did 
not  appear  until  31  years  later,  althougli  some  pioneering 
■was  done  in  the  meantime.  In  1883  Sir  Henry  Storks  first 
brought  eooperative  credit  to  the  official  notice  of  the  Indian 
Government.  In  the  early  nineties  unsuccessful  attempts 
to  introduce  it  were  made  by  the  Salvation  Army  and  by 
Lord  Macdonnell  in  the  United  Provinces  and  at  Mysore. 
In  1893  Lord  Wenlock  commissioned  Mr.  (now  Sir)  Freder- 
ick A.  Nicholson  on  special  duty  to  inquire  into  the  possi- 
bility of  introducing  into  the  Madras  Presidency  "a  system 
of  agricultural  or  other  land  banks."  In  1895  Sir  Frederick 
submitted  the  first  volume,  and  in  1897  the  second  volume, 
of  a  monumental  report.  This  report  (unfortunately  now 
out  of  print)  contains  an  account  of  all  such  banks  then  ex- 
isting in  Europe  and  the  United  States  and  is  the  best  and 
most  complete  treatise,  particularly  of  land  credit,  which  has 
been  published  in  the  English  language.  It  is  the  unrivaled 
classic  in  our  tongue  on  the  subjects  discussed  and  gives  more 
information  as  to  both  facts  and  principles  than  any  similar 
publication. 

It  wiU  be  noticed  that  Sir  Frederick's  instructions  were 
mainly  to  study  land  banks.  He  carried  them  out  to  the  let- 
ter but  made  a  thorough  investigation  also  of  cooperative 
credit  and  summed  up  his  report  in  two  words,  "find  Eaif- 
feisen."  This  conclusion  was  reached  after  consultation 
with  Henry  W.  Wolff,  "whose  extensive  knowledge  of  the 
principles  and  practice  of  cooperative  village  banking,"  says 
the  report,  "are  well  known,  and  whose  valuable  suggestions 
conununicated  through  the  Secretary  of  State  have  received 
our  most  careful  consideration."  The  report  revolutionized 
thought  in  official  British  India,  and  as  a  result  a  law  for 
cooperative  credit  was  placed  on  the  statute  books  with  the 
assistance  of  Mr.  Wolff,  now  the  most  prominent  authority 
on  popular  credit  in  English-speaking  countries.  The  spread 
of  cooperative  credit  in  British  India  since  the  passage  of 
this  law  makes  one  of  the  most  remarkable  chapters  in  the 
history  of  cooperation.  The  number  of  banks,  it  is  true,  is; 
yet  insignificant  in  comparison  with  the  financial  needs  of 


430  EUEAL   CREDITS 

the  multitudinous  population,  but  wherever  they  exist  they 
have  stamped  out  usury,  stimulated  thrift,  and  furnished 
easy  money  in  sufficient  quantities  to  many  poor  farmers  who 
never  before  could  get  a  rupee.  The  success  achieved  has 
prompted  the  governors  of  all  the  provinces  to  declare  that 
the  social  and  economic  regeneration  of  the  Hindustani 
farmers  wiU  come  through  cooperation.  Such  is  the  out- 
come in  that  enormous  country  of  the  study  of  Sir  Frederick 
A.  Nicholson  and  of  his  adviser,  Henry  W.  Wolff. 

The  British  India  cooperative  credit  law,  which  was  en- 
acted in  1904  and  amended  in  1912,  outliaes  in  a  general 
way  the  principles  of  cooperative  credit,  allows  limited  and 
unlimited  liability  of  members  of  the  societies  which  it  au- 
thorizes, permits  such  societies  to  form  central  banks,  unions 
and  federations,  and  empowers  the  provincial  governments 
to  prescribe  the  rules  and  regulations  for  their  organization 
and  management.  A  special  act  was  passed  for  the  protec- 
torate of  Baroda.  Naturally  there  are  some  slight  points  of 
difference  among  the  systems  in  the  various  provinces,  but 
the  societies  all  belong  to  either  one  of  the  two  classes  al- 
lowed, formerly  urban  and  rural,  but  now,  by  the  amend- 
ment to  the  law,  linodted  and  unlimited. 

When  the  liability  is  limited  by  shares,  no  person  may 
hold  shares  of  a  face  value  in  excess  of  1,000  rupees  ($324), 
nor  more  than  a  certain  portion  of  the  total  capital  as  deter- 
mined by  the  provincial  government,  subject  to  the  general 
regulation  that  this  portion  shall  not  be  more  than  one-fifth. 
The  by-laws  may  fix  the  mmiber  of  votes  which  any  one 
member  may  have.  Dividends  may  be  distributed  after  one- 
fourth  of  the  profits  have  been  set  aside  for  the  reserve. 
When  the  liability  is  unlimited  a  member  has  only  one  vote. 
All  profits  must  be  placed  in  the  reserve  until  that  fund 
reaches  a  certain  percentage  of  the  outstanding  obligations 
of  the  society  as  fixed  by  the  by-laws  or  the  provincial  act 
and  imtil  the  interest  on  loans  has  been  reduced  below  a 
rate  specified  in  the  by-laws.  After  that  a  rebate  may  be 
distributed  among  the  members  in  proportion  to  their  loans 
as  determined  by  the  by-laws. 


BEITISH  INDIA,  JAPAN,  EGYPT,  ETC.     431 

Neither  class  of  society  may  take  deposits  from  non-mem- 
bers nor  make  loans  to  them.  There  is  one  exception  to  this 
rule,  in  that  a  limited  society  may  lend  to  an  imlimited 
society  and  an  imlimited  society  may  lend  to  another  im- 
limited society.  The  privileges  accorded  to  both  classes  of 
societies  are  the  same.  A  cooperative  credit  society  has  a 
lien  on  the  crops  or  agricultural  produce  of  a  member  who  is 
in  debt  to  it  for  money  advanced  or  credit  extended  to  enable 
him  to  obtain  seed  or  fertilizer,  and  also  upon  any  livestock, 
implements,  machinery  or  raw  material  sold  by  the  society 
to  a  member  or  bought  by  such  member  with  money  lent  by 
the  society.  This  lien  may  be  enforced  against  the  rights 
of  prior  creditors.  Every  society  may  do  collective  buying 
and  selling  for  members  ia  addition  to  its  banking  busiuess, 
if  so  provided  in  its  by-laws.  A  large  number  of  societies 
exercise  this  right. 

All  cooperative  credit  societies  are  exempt  from  the  in- 
come tax,  stamp  duties  and  registration  fees.  Appropria- 
tions have  been  made  so  that  each  society  may  receive  an 
advance  from  the  state  equal  to  the  amount  of  the  deposits 
of  members.  The  societies  of  each  province  are  subject  to 
supervision  and  inspection  by  a  registrar  appointed  by  the 
provincial  government.  The  duties  of  this  ofBcial  are  far 
more  important  than  the  title  indicates,  because  besides  reg- 
istering, inspecting,  auditing  and  advising  existing  societies, 
he  is  required  to  organize  new  societies  wherever  possible  and 
to  propagate  the  cooperative  credit  idea  generally  in  his 
province.  In  fact,  the  development  and  direction  of  the 
cooperative  movement  in  British  India  rest  in  the  hands  of 
the  registrars,  and  they  are  given  wide  discretion  in  the  per- 
formance of  their  functions.  They  frequently  allow  the  cen- 
tral banks  to  inspect  and  audit  the  locals  in  the  first  instance 
but  do  not  yet  depend  entirely  upon  their  findings.  These 
central  banks,  which  may  admit  individuals  as  well  as  so- 
cieties as  members,  are  divided  into  three  classes :  those  which 
lend  exclusively  to  other  societies;  those  which  lend  princi- 
pally to  other  societies;  and  those  which  lend  principally  to 
individual  members. 


432  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

In  1911  there  were  in  British  India  4,957  rural  coopera- 
tive credit  societies  registered  under  the  laws.  Their  aver- 
age membership  was  28,  or  a  total  of  238,978.  In  addition 
there  were  415  urban  societies  and  60  central  banks.  The 
combined  working  capital  of  the  rural  societies  amounted  to 
11,018,863  rupees  ($3,570,111.61),  and  loans  to  10,389,674 
rupees  ($3,366,254.38).  One-half  (50.2  per  cent)  of  the 
working  capital  consisted  of  loans  from  other  societies;  13.7 
per  cent  of  loans  from  non-members,  usually  philanthropic 
persons,  savings  or  commercial  banks;  5.5  per  cent  of  loans 
from  the  Government;  13.3  per  cent  of  share  capital;  14.2 
per  cent  of  deposits  from  members;  and  3.1  per  cent  of  re- 
serves. The  loans  usually  ran  for  one  agricultural  season. 
The  interest  rates  varied,  the  lowest  being  6%  per  cent  in 
Madras  and  the  highest  18%  per  cent  in  Bengal.  But  these 
rates  were  far  below  the  average  outside  the  cooperative  so- 
cieties, where  24  to  150  per  cent  is  charged.  The  size  of  in- 
dividual loans  was  $5.15  to  $32.40.  With  few  exceptions 
the  rural  credit  societies  have  imlimited  liability,  due  per- 
haps to  the  fact  that  the  members  use  their  savings  in  mak- 
ing deposits  instead  of  in  buying  shares  in  order  that  their 
societies  may  receive  larger  advances  of  working  capital  from 
the  state. 

The  central  banks  in  1911  had  a  combined  working  capi- 
tal of  6,040,275  rupees  ($1,957,049.10).  Over  one-half  of 
this  (51  per  cent)  consisted  of  loans  from  non-members;  3.68 
per  cent  of  loans  from  other  societies;  1.05  per  cent  of  loans 
from  the  Government ;  12.81  per  cent  of  share  capital ;  30.07 
per  cent  of  deposits  of  members;  and  the  rest  of  reserves. 
The  outstanding  loans  amoimted  to  5,703,040  rupees 
($1,847,784.96).  The  loans  ran  for  over  a  year  but  never 
longer  than  two  years.  The  interest  rates  were  somewhat 
less  than  those  of  the  local  banks.  'So  unions  or  federations 
have  been  formed  yet  in  British  India,  but  a  few  of  the  cen- 
tral banks  serve  as  such. 

Over  60  per  cent  of  the  population  of  Japan  is  agricul- 
tural but  only  a  small  portion  of  the  land  is  cultivated. 


BRITISH  INDIA,  JAPAN,  EGYPT,  ETC.     433 

The  mountainous  interior  is  left  to  forests  and  natural 
growths  and  the  farming  is  done  along  the  coasts  or  in  the 
valleys.  Cultivation  is  intensive  to  the  last  degree.  Over 
87  per  cent  of  the  farmers  make  a  living  for  families  of  four 
to  six  persons  on  garden  patches  of  less  than  five  acres. 
Three  or  four  crops  are  raised  a  year  in  the  tropical  and 
at  least  two  in  the  temperate  regions,  so  the  country  depends 
on  importation  only  to  a  slight  degree  for  the  necessary 
staples  of  food  and  clothing. 

Association  for  mutual  assistance  is  an  old  practice 
among  Japanese  farmers,  just  as  it  is  in  Europe.  At  the 
abolition  ofC  the  feudal  system  a  secret  aid  society  was 
founded  by  Shin-en  Sato,  while  about  the  time  that  Schulze- 
Delitzseh  started  his  first  bank  in  Germany,  the  famous  peas- 
ant sage,  Sontoku  Ninimiya,  formed  the  Hotoku-sha,  the 
original  Japanese  cooperative  credit  society.  Many  institu- 
tions of  this  type  stiU  exist,  organized  either  as  joint-stock 
companies,  associations,  or  cooperative  societies  with  limited 
or  unlimited  liability.  Some  of  them  are  managed  by  public 
authorities,  others  by  private  individuals,  but  all  are  operated 
without  lucrative  object.  Their  principal  business  is  to 
maintain  warehouses  for  receiving  and  grading  rice  and  issu- 
ing warrants  against  it.  By  this  means  growers  are  able 
safely  to  store  their  crop  until  a  good  market  arises  and  to 
derive  all  the  advantages  of  collective  selling.  These  ware- 
house concerns  also  grant  loans  on  the  security  of  the  stored 
rice,  and  in  addition  to  their  regular  business,  strive  to  in- 
duce farmers  to  use  commercial  fertilizer  and  modern  im- 
plements and  machinery  and  to  exercise  care  in  harvesting, 
cleaning  and  sacking  their  produce.  Many  hold  expositions 
and  demonstration  shows  and  have  become  strong  factors 
in  their  localities  for  the  improvement  of  agriculture  gen- 
erally. 

Cooperation  of  the  European  kind,  however,  did  not  make 
its  appearance  in  Japan  until  after  the  law  on  cooperative 
societies  was  enacted  by  the  Imperial  Diet  on  April  8,  1909. 
Since  then  it  has  made  enormous  strides.  This  law,  with  its 
amendments,  ranks  with  the  best  which  have  been  drafted 


434  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

and  is  in  all  respects  in  keeping  with  the  progressive  spirit 
displayed  by  Japan  ever  since  she  opened  her  ports  to  the 
light  of  western  civilization.  Cooperative  societies  are  di- 
vided under  this  law  into  four  classes-^credit,  purchase,  pro- 
duction and  sales.  Any  of  the  last  three  may  have  credit 
as  one  of  their  objects,  and,  in  fact,  all  objects  may  be  com- 
bined in  the  same  society.  The  societies  may  choose  either 
unlimited  liability,  or  liability  limited  to  the  members'  sub- 
scriptions, or  liability  limited  to  a  fixed  number  of  times  of 
the  subscription. 

A  cooperative  society  must  have  at  least  seven  members 
and  may  limit  the  mrniber  above  that  minimum.  It  must 
confine  its  operations  within  an  area,  usually  a  commune, 
fixed  by  the  articles  of  agreement.  The  articles  of  agree- 
ment must  be  approved  by  the  prefect.  The  rights  and 
duties  of  members  of  the  society  and  the  rules  for  admission 
and  expulsion  are  laid  down  in  the  civil  and  commercial 
codes. 

Cooperative  societies  may  unite  to  form  federations, 
which  may  act  as  supervisors,  as  regional  banks  and  regional 
establishments  for  collective  buying  and  selling  for  adher- 
ents, and  as  centers  for  protecting  and  promoting  their  com- 
mon interests  and  for  propagating  and  developing  coopera- 
tion. Societies  for  production,  purchase  and  sales  may  join 
credit  federations,  but  pure  credit  societies  may  not  belong 
to  federations  which  have  any  other  object  than  credit.  The 
federations  may  assume  limited  liability  or  a  liability  limited 
to  a  certain  number  of  times  the  subscriptions  of  adherents. 
Each  federation's  sphere  is  limited  to  a  province,  except 
where  it  is  authorized  by  competent  authority  to  operate 
over  two  or  more  small  provinces.  The  managers  and  in- 
spectors of  a  federation  are  elected  at  the  annual  meeting 
from  among  the  officials  of  adhering  societies,  unless  it  be 
deemed  advisable  to  choose  outsiders,  in  which  event  the 
selection  must  be  confirmed  by  the  prefect. 

Over  all  is  the  Central  Association  of  Cooperative  So- 
cieties, which  serves  as  the  national  organ  of  both  the  local 
societies  and  the  federations.    This  body  was  formed  by  vir- 


BRITISH  INDIA,  JAPAN,  EGYPT,  ETC.     435 

tue  of  a  law  which  defines  its  purposes  and  powers  and  de- 
clares it  to  be  constituted  with  the  view  of  encouraging  the 
formation  of  new  societies  and  federations,  of  improving 
those  already  formed,  and  of  facilitating  financial  and  com- 
mercial relations  among  the  various  units  of  the  system.  Co- 
operative societies  are  exempt  from  the  payment  of  the  income 
tax  and  the  tax  on  business  but  not  from  registration  fees. 

In  1912  there  were  9,349  cooperative  credit  societies  in 
Japan  with  over  980,000  members,  and  30  federations,  not 
counting  the  central  federation.  Two  of  the  federations  had 
a  liability  extended  to  a  certain  number  of  times  the  sub- 
scriptions of  adherents,  while  the  rest  have  strictly  limited 
liability.  Of  the  locals,  47.90  per  cent  had  a  liabilily  limited 
to  members'  subscriptions,  50.08  per  cent  unlimited  liability, 
and  3.03  per  cent  a  liability  limited  to  a  certain  number  of 
times  members'  subscriptions.  The  average  membership 
during  the  past  four  years  was  105  per  society,  of  whom 
81.93  per  cent  were  farmers.  Of  the  total  number,  3,676 
societies  had  credit  and  savings  as  their  only  object,  but  4,635 
economic  societies  also  had  these  objects,  thus  making  7,301 
societies  which  did  a  banking  business. 

On  account  of  this  frequent  combining  of  various  objects 
in  the  same  society,  it  is  difficult  to  give  exact  statistics  of 
the  business  done  by  the  credit  societies  alone.  In  1913  the 
working  capital  for  aU  societies  was  $31,314,535,  including 
sums  paid  on  shares,  deposits,  reserves,  special  funds  and 
borrowed  money.  This  figure  represents  an  infinite  number 
of  little  items  and  transactions,  because  the  average  sum  paid 
in  on  shares  was  $7.93,  while  deposits  of  five  cents  were  by 
no  means  rare.  By  last  reports  the  highest  interest  rate  for 
loans  was  18.3  per  cent,  and  for  deposits  13.3  per  cent  per 
annum;  the  lowest  rates  were  13  per  cent  and  six  per  centj 
respectively.  These  excessive  rates  for  loans,  however,  are 
much  less  than  are  exacted  from  unorganized  farmers  in 
Japan. 

In  1908  Prince  Hussein,  now  Premier  of  Egypt,  ap- 
pointed a  commission  in  behalf  of  the  Khedivial  Society  of 


436  ETJEAL   CEEDITS 

'Agriculture  to  study  agricultural  cooperation  and  to  prepare 
a  bill  on  the  subject  for  Egypt.  A  bill  -was  drafted  with  the 
assistance  of  Mr.  Eibet  of  the  French  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture, but  it  was  not  accepted  by  the  Egyptian  Government. 
Prince  Hussein  has  not  yet  accomplished  his  main  object, 
but  he  has  succeeded  in  awakening  a  public  interest  which 
now  seems  likely  to  develop  into  a  general  movement  for  the 
introduction  of  cooperation  in  Egypt. 

Among  the  members  of  Prince  Hussein's  commission  was 
Omar  Lufty  Bey,  who,  if  the  movement  continues  to  sub- 
stantial results,  will  be  known  as  the  father  of  Egyptian 
cooperation,  because  he  founded  at  Cairo  in  1910  the  first 
cooperative  society  on  the  land  watered  by  the  NUe.  This 
society's  object  is  credit  for  small  traders,  and  while  many 
farmers  are  found  among  its  350  members,  it  is  far  from 
being  agricultural.  Its  organization  and  business  methods, 
however,  have  been  taken  as  models  for  all  rural  credit  so- 
cieties so  far  formed  in  Egypt. 

Owing  to  the  absence  of  the  necessary  law,  Omar  Lufty 
Bey  could  not  establish  his  society  on  the  collective  liability, 
limited  or  unlimited,  of  its  members.  He  had  to  form  it  as 
a  joint-stock  corporation.  But  in  order  to  give  it  some  coop- 
erative features  he  inserted  two  articles  in  the  charter  which 
provide  that  shares  may  not  be  transferred  except  with  the 
consent  of  the  managing  board  of  the  society,  and  that  credit 
may  be  accorded  only  to  members,  unless  the  funds  are  in 
excess  of  their  requirements,  when  loans  may  be  made  to 
outsiders.  This  society  had  in  1913  a  paid-up  capital  of 
$35,000,  and  upon  this  made  $105,000  of  loans.  These  fig- 
ures are  too  small  to  have  any  material  efEect  upon  the  multi- 
tudes of  moneyless  and  debt-encumbered  fellaheen,  but  the 
fact  that  the  society  can  lend  at  7%  per  cent  interest  and 
make  handsome  profits  in  places  and  among  a  class  of  people 
where  the  Greek  usurers  will  not  let  their  money  go  for 
less  than  30  to  35  per  cent  per  annum,  furnishes  a  striking 
example  of  the  potency  of  cooperation  even  when  it  is  held 
together  simply  by  the  spirit  unsupported  by  legalized  form. 

Only  a  few  days  after  Omar  Lufty  Bey  founded  his  so- 


BRITISH  INDIA,  JAPAN,  EGYPT,  ETC.     437 

ciety,  an  exclusively  rural  cooperative  credit  society  was 
started  at  Shubrah-el-Namlah.  This  also  was  successful,  and 
by  granting  its  97  members  one-year  loans  at  six  per  cent 
proves  conclusively  that  usury  can  be  abolished  by  coopera- 
tion even  among  the  smallest  farmers  along  the  Nile.  This 
society  does  most  of  its  business  by  buying  seed,  fertilizer,  and 
coal  to  seU  to  members  at  three  per  cent  above  the  purchase 
price  for  cash,  or  at  seven  per  cent  above  on  credit.  In  1912 
there  were  nine  agricultural  credit  societies  in  Egypt  or- 
ganized like  the  first  of  those  described  ard  operating  like 
the  second. 

In  1901  the  French  Government  created  an  agricultural 
mutual  credit  system  in  Algeria  and  supplied  it  with  funds 
by  a  method  similar  to  that  used  in  the  mother  country. 
The  Bank  of  Algeria  was  required  to  place  $600,000  at  the 
disposal  of  the  regional  banks  and  engage  itself  to  certain 
annual  payments  in  addition  thereto.  In  1910  there  were 
41  regional  and  338  local  banks  with  10,663  members.  Up 
to  that  year  the  Bank  of  Algeria  had  turned  over  to  the  state 
$1,050,000,  most  of  which  had  been  advanced  to  the  regional 
banks  for  nine  years  without  interest.  Their  combined  capi- 
tal was  $373,013,  and  reserves  $104,399.  The  banks  admit 
natives  and  Europeans  indiscriminately. 

The  system  was  extended  in  1904  to  Tunis,  where  there 
are  now  one  regional  bank  and  32  local  banks  with  671  mem- 
bers. The  regional  bank  of  Tunis  has  a  capital  of  $16,000 
and  the  state  has  advanced  it  four  times  that  amount  with- 
out interest  out  of  the  funds  coming  through  the  Bank  of 
Algeria.  Interest  rates  on  loans  for  members  in  both  coun- 
tries are  generally  5.5  per  cent. 

Very  few  natives  belong  to  the  cooperative  banks  in 
Tunis,  for  the  reason  that  the  Mohammedan  religion  forbids 
the  taking  of  interest.  Special  institutions  have  been  estab- 
lished for  the  natives,  which  are  called  provident  societies. 
They  are  managed  by  the  native  chief  and  government  offi- 
cials and  are  financed  by  an  extra  land  tax  levied  on  the 
natives.    Part  of  their  funds  are  also  composed  of  donations. 


438  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

legacies  and  the  state  subsidies  from  the  Bank  of  Algeria. 
Some  of  these  societies  have  departed  from  strict  observance 
of  religious  priaciples  and  borrow  money  when  needed  and 
make  loans  to  members.  But  their  main  and  ordinary  busi- 
ness is  to  make  loans  in  kind  and  relieve  members  in  dis- 
tress. About  150,000  natives  belong  to  these  societies  and 
are  able  to  get  advances  for  food  and  seed  at  12  per  cent  on 
short  time  and  11  per  cent  on  long  term,  if  secured  by  real- 
estate  mortgages.  Formerly  the  natives  paid  18  to  150  per 
cent. 

In  1910  the  Governor  of  French  West  Africa  promul- 
gated a  decree  for  the  formation  of  thrift  societies,  mutual 
aid  societies  and  land  credit  societies  for  the  natives.  A 
six  months'  residence  in  a  district  is  a  necessary  qualification 
for  membership.  The  wording  of  the  decree  indicates  that 
membership  is  compulsory  for  all  such  persons.  The  interest 
rate  on  loans  in  money  is  limited  to  five  per  cent  per  anrmTn 
and  on  loans  in  kind  to  25  per  cent  per  annum. 

In  a  few  of  the  other  colonies  of  European  Powers  coop- 
erative credit  has  been  organized.  A  rural  credit  society  of 
the  Eaiffeisen  type  was  formed  in  Java  in  1904  by  de  Wolff 
von  Westerode,  a  public  official  of  the  Dutch  provincial  gov- 
ernment. A  credit  society  with  liability  limited  to  about  30 
times  the  face  value  of  the  shares  exists  in  Windhoek,  the 
capital  of  German  Southwest  Africa.  It  has  125  members 
and  belongs  to  the  Imperial  Federation  of  Germany.  There 
is  one  credit  society  in  Guinea,  one  in  the  Barbadoes,  and  one 
in  Jamaica,  all  following  more  or  less  closely  the  Eaiffeisen 
type. 


CHAPTER  XXXI 

GEEAT    BEITAIN,    lEELAKD,    CANADA,    AND    THE 
UNITED  STATES 

Irish  Agrieultural  Organization. — Sir  Horace  Plunkett. — Doneraile 
Credit  Society. — ^Progress  of  Eural  Cooperative  Credit  Not  Sat- 
isfactory.— Agricultural  Organization  Society  for  England  and 
Wales. — Organization  and  Management. — Scottish  Agricultural 
Organization  Society. — Caisse  Populaire  of  Quebec. — ^Legisla- 
tion of  1906. — Cooperative  Credit  in  French  Canada. — Coopera- 
tive Credit  Among  Jewish  Farmers  of  the  United  States.— Gen- 
eral Agitation  of  Eural  Credit  Idea. — Jewish  Eural  Cooperative 
Banks. — Other  Cooperative  Attempts  by  Jews  in  North  and 
South  America. 

The  agricultural  cooperative  movement  in  the  United 
Kingdom  is  guided  by  the  Irish  Agricultural  Organization 
Society,  the  Scottish  Agricultural  Organization  Society,  the 
Agricultural  Organization  Society  for  England  and  Wales, 
and  the  Joint  Board  for  Agricultural  Organization,  which 
links  them  all  together.  These  four  bodies  have  for  their 
exclusive  object  the  aid  and  development  of  agriculture  and 
rural  industries  through  cooperation.  They  are  strictly  non- 
profit making,  siace  the  law  under  which  they  are  chartered 
forbids  such  associations  to  engage  in  lucrative  business. 
The  trading  end  of  the  movement  is  cared  for  in  England 
and  Wales  by  the  Farmers'  Central  Trading  Board,  which 
in  its  turn  is  linked  up  with  similar  boards  in  Ireland  and 
Scotland  by  the  Joint  Agricultural  Board  of  Trade  for  the 
four  countries. 

The  movement  directed  by  this  excellently  arranged  sys- 
tem was  started  in  Ireland  in  1889.  Although  prosperous 
now,  through  the  introduction  of  cooperation,  the  land-pur- 
chase acts  and  other  legislative  reforms,  the  misery  of  Ire- 

439 


440  EHRAL   CEEDITS 

land  at  that  period  is  well  known.  "The  country,"  said  Har- 
old Barbour,  "had  appealed  to  God,  to  the  state,  to  humanity, 
for  sympathy,  for  aid,  for  dollars,  and  had  become  a  mendi- 
cant among  the  nations."  Steps  had  already  been  taken,  it 
is  true,  to  solve  the  land  question,  but  the  "fair  rents,"  al- 
though fixed  by  the  courts  at  reasonable  figures,  were  more 
than  the  tenants  could  pay.  Nearly  one-half  of  the  inhabi- 
tants of  Ireland  had  emigrated  beyond  seas,  and  most  of 
those  who  remained  were  living  in  mud  huts  or  squalid  hov- 
els, inflamed  with  mutinous  rage  against  the  Government. 
The  plight  of  the  farming  classes  was  the  most  wretched  of 
all,  for  on  account  of  their  crude  methods  of  cultivation  and 
marketing,  foreign  competitors  were  underselling  them  in 
the  staple  products  for  which  the  soil  was  best  adapted  and 
the  meager  gains  were  shared  between  the  landlords  and  the 
"gombeen"  men. 

In  the  midst  of  this  distress,  when  the  decaying  state  of 
agriculture  was  demoralizing  the  Irish  farmers  economically 
and  socially,  Mr.  (now  Sir)  Horace  Plunkett,  who  had  been 
ranching  for  a  number  of  years  in  western  United  States, 
returned  to  his  native  land  and  resolved  to  devote  his  life  to 
rescuing  the  Irish  farmers  from  their  miserable  situation. 
This  was,  in  his  opinion,  due  in  a  large  measure  to  their  own 
improvidence  and  disinclination  to  farm  and  market  their 
crops  in  a  scientific  and  modern  way.  Sir  Horace  was  fa- 
miliar with  what  had  been  done  by  Eaiffeisen  in  Germany, 
and,  inspired  by  his  principles,  with  a  few  enthusiastic  pio- 
neers he  mapped  out  a  campaign  to  persuade  the  Irish  farm- 
ers to  organize  agriculture  on  cooperative  lines  and  to  induce 
the  state  to  give  to  them  the  same  kind  of  assistance  which 
the  German  farmers  received  from  the  Government.  By 
1894  the  campaign  had  progressed  sufficiently  to  show  that 
cooperation  was  congenial  to  the  Irish  spirit,  and  the  Irish 
Agricultural  Organization  Society  was  formed  at  Dublin 
under  the  presidency  of  Sir  Horace  Plunkett  to  direct  and 
further  the  movement. 

This  Society  for  propaganda  and  organization  work  so- 
licits and  has  received  aid  from  the  state  but  it  is  not  con- 


GEEAT  BEITAIN  AND  lEELAND,  ETC.     441 

neeted  with  the  Govemment.  It  is  composed  of  private  in- 
dividuals and  afiBliated  local  cooperative  societies  and  depends 
in  the  main  upon  their  fees  arid  voluntary  contributions  for 
support.  Since  its  foundation  the  Society  has  expended  over 
$500,000,  and  never  has  money  been  spent  for  better  purpose 
or  to  greater  effect.  Ai  the  beginning  of  1913  there  were 
in  Ireland  934  rural  cooperative  societies  with  97,318  mem- 
bers. Their  annual  turnover  exceeded  $13,000,000,  and  the 
total  turnover  since  the  first  society  was  formed  has  reached 
nearly  $100,000,000. 

The  first  Irish  cooperative  association  was  a  creamery,  and 
creamery  associations  still  constitute  the  largest  class  among 
Irish  cooperative  societies.  The  first  credit  society  was  not 
started  until  February,  1895,  when  the  movement  was  over 
five  years  old.  Plunkett,  who  had  read  Henry  W.  Wolff's 
books  on  agricultural  banks,  attended  a  meeting  on  coopera- 
tive credit  in  London,  which  was  addressed  by  Mr.  Wolff  and 
was  deeply  impressed  by  what  he  heard.  "You  have  con- 
verted me,"  said  he  to  Wolff,  "and  I  want  you  to  come  over 
and  convert  my  colleagues."  Mr.  Wolff  went  to  Dublin,  con- 
vinced the  Irish  Agricultural  Organization  Society  that 
credit  of  the  Eaiffeisen  type  should  be  developed  along  with 
the  general  cooperative  movement,  and  the  Doneraile  bank 
was  the  result. 

The  area  of  the  Doneraile  credit  society  is  so  restricted 
that  the  members  are  all  acquainted  with  one  another.  They 
are  liable  without  limit  for  all  obligations  the  bank  incurs. 
The  loans  are  made  only  for  productive  or  provident  pur- 
poses, and  must  be  used  for  the  specific  object  for  which 
they  are  granted.  They  are  for  short  terms  adjusted  to  the 
needs  of  each  ease,  and  draw  five  to  6^  per  cent  interest,  but 
are  never  granted  except  on  the  security  of  two  iudorsers. 
The  society  distributes  no  dividends,  bonuses  or  rebates. 
Profits  are  written  to  the  reserve  with  the  hope  of  making 
that  fund  sufficient  in  time  for  all  operations  and  for  reduc- 
ing the  rate  of  interest  to  borrowers.  Money  for  loans  comes 
from  the  commercial  banks,  depositors  and  the  state.  No 
person  may  be  a  member  unless  he  is  sober,  industrious,  of 


442  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

a  friendly  nature  and  known  to  be  strictly  honest,  and  it  is 
the  duty  of  the  management,  composed  of  a  chairman  and  a 
committee,  to  see  that  only  such  persons  are  admitted.  No 
one  in  the  management  except  the  secretary  receives  compen- 
sation. 

There  are  at  present  in  Ireland  236  rural  cooperative 
credit  societies  with  19,505  members,  aU  organized  and  man- 
aged like  the  one  at  Doneraile.  The  oflScers  in  many  in- 
stances are  priests  or  school  teachers  who  joined  the  societies 
especially  to  serve  in  that  capacity.  The  commercial  banks 
make  advances  to  the  credit  societies  at  a  imiform  rate  of 
four  per  cent  irrespective  of  the  fluctuation  of  the  rate  of  the 
Bank  of  England.  The  societies  pay  between  three  and  four 
per  cent  on  deposits,  and  all  have  received  sums  of  $250, 
$750  or  $1,000  for  initial  expenses  from  the  state  or  coimty 
councils  in  the  way  of  loans  at  3  per  cent.  About  one-fourth 
of  their  working  capital  is  now  obtained  from  these  public 
sources,  and  in  the  early  stages  over  one-half  was  so  ob- 
tained. 

In  spite  of  this  outside  assistance  rural  cooperative  credit 
has  not  made  satisfactory  progress  in  Ireland.  Of  the  total 
number  176  rural  credit  societies  are  active,  the  rest  being 
merely  skeleton  organizations  or  in  a  stagnant  condition. 
Only  80  per  cent  of  them  render  annual  reports  to  the  Irish 
Agricultural  Organization  Society,  which  is  supposed  to 
audit  their  accounts  and  supervise  their  affairs.  Eenewal  of 
loans  is  a  flagrant  practice,  and  the  state  has  been  compelled 
on  28  occasions  to  resort  to  the  courts  for  the  recovery  of  its 
advances.  These  advances  and  the  deposits  lie  idle  in  many 
societies,  causing  a  loss  of  interest  which  eats  up  all  profits 
in  31  of  them.  The  Irish  Agricultural  Organization  Society 
attributes  the  trouble  to  the  fact  that  most  of  the  credit  so- 
cieties operate  on  too  small  a  margin  and  that  the  managers 
prefer  to  do  business  at  all  to  doing  it  without  any  profit. 
Fires  and  unexpectedly  heavy  expenses  have  occasioned  losses 
in  some  cases.  The  Society  does  not  seem  to  think  that  state 
aid  may  have  weakened  the  spirit  of  self-help  and  independ- 
ence.    Critics  of  the  Irish  system,  however,  are  inclined  to 


GEEAT  BEITAIN  AND   lEELAND,  ETC.      443 

lay  stress  upon  this  point.  They  also  believe  that  the  Irish 
credit  societies  should  be  given  trading  powers.  No  rural 
credit  system  has  succeeded  greatly  except  where  the  credit 
societies  do  collective  buying  and  selling  or  else  are  sjmdi- 
cated  by  identity  of  membership  with  purchasing  and  distrib- 
uting societies.  Farmers  will  not  organize  credit  societies  or 
assume  the  expense,  care,  risk  and  responsibility  of  their 
management  unless  such  banks  are  empowered  to  utilize  the 
funds  "Obtained  by  shares  or  deposits  for  some  definite  objects 
of  economy  and  convenience.  Thrift  stimulated  by  divi- 
dends or  interest,  so  effective  in  the  cities,  is  no  induce- 
ment to  farmers,  who,  as  a  rule,  find  immediate  use  for 
all  money  they  make  and  so  have  none  to  lay  aside  in  the 
banks  for  loans  to  others  at  the  rates  they  are  able  to 
offer. 

The  Agricultural  Organization  Society  (London)  for 
England  and  Wales  was  formed  in  1900  by  the  coalition  of 
the  National  Agricultural  Union  formed  by  Lord  Winchil- 
sea  in  1892  and  the  British  Agricultural  Organization  So- 
ciety formed  in  1899  by  W.  L.  Charleton,  a  pupil  of  Sir 
Horace  Plunkett.  In  the  beginning  this  body  was  a  coun- 
terpart of  the  Irish  Society  and  was  composed  of  private 
individuals.  In  May,  1913,  however,  it  was  entirely  recon- 
structed, and  became  a  semi-public  institution  managed  by 
a  board  of  36  governors,  of  whom  13  are  appointed  by  the 
Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries,  two  by  the  County  Coun- 
cils Association,  two  by  the  Cooperative  Union,  two  eoopted 
by  the  governors,  and  18,  including  the  president,  elected 
by  aflBliated  societies.  The  county  councils  also  are  strongly 
represented  on  the  committees  which  manage  the  branches 
of  the  society  in  the  various  districts.  The  Cooperative 
Union  existed  before  cooperation  spread  to  agriculture  in 
England  and  is  composed  mostly  of  urban  societies. 

The  conversion  of  the  Agricultural  Organization  Society 
from  a  private  to  a  semi-public  institution  was  prompted  by 
its  desire  to  receive  subsidies  from  the  state.  The  act  relat- 
ing to  the  Development  Commission  provides  that  the  Treas- 


4M  EUKAL   GEEDITS 

ury  may  make  grants  or  loans  to  any  association  of  persons 
which  the  Commission  may  recommend.  The  Commission 
demanded  that  the  changes  mentioned  should  be  made  before 
it  would  recommend  it  to  the  Treasury,  so  the  Society  acted 
accordingly.  The  subsidies  were  desired  chiefly  for  promot- 
ing small  holdings  and  allotment  cooperative  associations. 
Sixteen  of  these  associations  have  been  formed.  Thus  the 
activities  of  the  Agricultural  Organization  Society  for  Eng- 
land and  Wales  extend  to  real-estate  credit,  and  this  together 
with  its  semi-public  character  are  the  chief  points  of  differ- 
ence between  it  and  its  Irish  prototype.  Nevertheless,  it 
depends  mainly  on  voluntary  contributions  and  the  fees 
of  aflBliated  societies  for  financial  support.  It  publishes 
an  oflBcial  organ  Cooperation  in  Agriculture^  a  periodical 
similar  to  the  Irish  Homestead^  published  by  the  Irish  So- 
ciety. 

In  1913  there  were  476  cooperative  societies  belonging  to 
the  Agricultural  Organization  Society,  with  45,000  mem- 
bers, and  all  imposed  unlimited  liability.  The  aggregate 
money  value  of  their  transactions  for  the  preceding  year  was 
nearly  $10,000,000.  Of  these  societies  46  with  800  members 
were  for  credit.  Their  total  turnover  was  less  than  $10,000. 
Only  21  of  them  made  loans,  and  the  aggregate  was  under 
$7,500.  So  rural  cooperative  credit  in  England  and  Wales, 
as  in  Ireland,  is  making  poor  progress.  The  reasons  as- 
signed for  its  slow  growth  are  the  reluctance  of  the  farmers 
to  borrow  in  cash,  to  show  their  financial  needs  to  their 
neighbors,  and  to  assume  unlimited  liability.  Moreover, 
there  does  not  seem  to  be  any  pressing  necessily  for  coopera- 
tive credit  societies,  since  the  ordinary  banks  and  merchants 
are  willing  to  extend  credit  where  required  on  easy  terms 
at  fair  interest  rates. 

A  central  bank  was  organized  for  the  cooperative  societies 
of  England  and  Wales  in  1908.  This  is  a  joint-stock  com- 
pany with  liability  limited  by  shares,  of  which  no  individual 
may  hold  more  than  $1,000.  Affiliated  societies  may  hold 
above  that  amount.  Dividends  of  more  than  five  per  cent  per 
annum  may  not  be  declared.    The  establishment  of  this  bank. 


GEEAT  BRITAIN  AND  IRELAND,  ETC.     445 

however,  was  premature,  and  it  has  not  been  of  much  use. 
In  1913,  after  the  Central  Cooperative  Bank  proved  useless, 
the  President  of  the  Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries  in- 
duced 20  leading  joint-stock  banks  with  branches  in  rural 
districts  to  sign  a  letter  offering  to  assist  in  the  formation 
of  rural  cooperative  credit  societies  and  to  grant  them  loans 
and  take  part  in  the  annual  audit  of  their  accounts,  allowing 
them  to  have  the  free  services  of  the  banks'  treasurers,  on 
the  understanding,  however,  that  this  would  not  involve 
membership  in  the  societies.  The  loans  which  the  banks  are 
willing  to  grant  are  subject  to  recall  on  demand  and  may 
not  extend  for  over  one  year. 

The  Scottish  Agricultural  Organization  Society  (Edin- 
burgh) was  formed  in  1905.  It  is  composed  of  voluntary 
contributors  and  affiliated  societies,  and  is  a  private  associa- 
tion Kke  the  Irish  Society.  In  1913  there  were  106  coopera- 
tive associations  belonging  to  the  Scottish  Society,  but  none 
of  them  was  for  credit.  The  abundance  of  facilities  af- 
forded by  the  branches  and  agencies  of  the  ordinary  banks 
is  the  reason  given  for  the  absence  of  cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties in  Scotland. 

The  first  cooperative  bank  on  the  American  continent 
was  started  at  Levis  in  the  province  of  Quebec  on  December 
6,  1900.  As  there  was  then  no  law  on  cooperation  in  the 
Province,  this  bank,  called  the  Caisse  Populaire,  was  formed 
simply  as  an  association.  The  first  sum  which  it  received 
was  ten  cents,  paid  by  one  of  its  members  in  an  instalment 
on  his  share.  At  the  end  of  the  first  month  it  had  taken  in 
only  $242.80,  but  in  1912  the  amount  paid  in  on  shares  was 
$114,343,  and  on  deposits  $53,564,  while  its  reserve  was 
$11,741.53.  On  June  30,  1914,  the  total  assets  were  $304,- 
985.92.  The  turnover  for  the  preceding  12  months  was 
$2,107,394.77,  while  the  7,208  loans  granted  to  that  date 
aggregated  $1,396,916.66.  About  one-half  of  these  loans 
were  for  sums  varying  between  $10  and  $100.  To  give  exact 
figures,  out  of  3,549  loans,  601  loans  were  for  $10  or  less. 


446  ETJEAi   CEEDITS 

898  for  $25  or  less,  961  for  $50  or  less,  493  for  $75  or  less, 
and  96  for  $100  or  less.  It  is  claimed  that  the  other  half  of 
the  loans  were  for  similar  sir-all  sums. 

Thus  the  Caisse  Populaire  is  distinctly  a  bank  for  small 
credit,  as  its  name  indicates,  for  the  people.  It  has  never 
lost  a  cent.  It  now  has  1,240  members  among  the  town  and 
country  folk  in  its  vicinity,  and  its  influence  has  spread  far 
and  wide  from  Levis.  Its  success  and  fame  has  inspired  the 
formation  of  120  banks  of  the  same  kind  in  Quebec,  19  in 
Ontario,  and  30  in  the  United  States,  and  has  brought  about 
the  enactment  of  a  law  for  cooperative  associations  in  Que- 
bec and  also  a  law  on  credit  unions  in  Massachusetts,  which 
was  taken  as  the  basis  of  the  legislation  on  cooperative  credit 
in  New  York,  Wisconsin  and  Texas. 

The  founder  of  the  Levis  bank  was  Alphonse  Desjardins, 
who  still  is  its  president  and  the  promoter  of  many  of  the 
other  banks.  Mr.  Desjardins  began  the  work  which  has  led 
to  these  remarkable  results  after  15  long  years  of  study,  dur- 
ing which  he  made  an  exhaustive  investigation  of  the  cooper- 
ative credit  systems  in  Europe  and  consulted  the  most  re- 
nowned of  the  European  leaders  in.  cooperation.  The  plan 
which  he  finally  adopted  was  based  on  the  principles  of  Luz- 
zatti  of  Italy,  and  imposes  no  liability  whatever  on  members 
for  the  obligations  of  the  bank.  The  form  of  the  adminis- 
tration and  management,  however,  says  Mr.  Desjardins,  "ia 
the  main  is  exactly  the  same  as  that  which  is  found  in  the 
uncapitalized  savings  banks  in  the  United  States,  with  the 
exception  that  the  deposits  are  used  by  the  very  persons  who 
make  them." 

Owing  to  the  absence  of  proper  laws  on  cooperation  in 
Canada,  Mr.  Desjardins  remained  ia  doubt  for  some  time  as 
to  whether  to  make  a  practical  application  of  the  ideas  he 
had  evolved,  but  Mr.  Henry  W.  Wolff,  the  authority  on  coop- 
eration in  England,  advised  him  to  go  ahead  without  the 
laws.  This  advice  was  followed,  and  Mr.  Desjardins  became 
the  American  pioneer  of  cooperative  credit.  Mr.  Wolff  has 
recently  declared  that  the  origination  of  the  Canadian  type 
of  bank  entitles  Mr.  Desjardins  to  as  much  praise  as  has 


GEEAT  BKITAIN  AND  lEFLAND,   ETC.      447 

been  bestowed  on  the  founders  of  the  systems  of  France  and 
Italy.  The  cooperative  form  of  organization  and  administra- 
tion appeared  in  the  United  States  through  the  building 
and  loan  associations,  however,  many  years  before  Mr.  Des- 
jardins  used  it  for  personal  credit  in  Canada. 

The  operations  and  members  of  the  Caisse  Populaire  are 
confined  to  a  single  parish,  and  women  and  children  as  well 
as  men  may  join,  no  matter  how  small  their  contributions 
may  be.  Mr.  Des jar  dins  has  succeeded  in  making  his  bank 
a  social  institution  for  encouraging  habits  of  thrift  and 
assisting  the  worthy  poor  who  are  in  need  of  credit.  The 
services  of  the  bank,  both  as  regards  the  granting  of  loans 
and  the  receiving  of  deposits,  are  restricted  to  members,  and 
in  this  respect  it  differs  from  most  of  the  European  banks 
which  accept  deposits  from  anybody.  The  interest  rate  on 
deposits  is  generally  three  per  cent.  The  Caisse  Populaire 
has  no  religious  character,  but  practically  all  its  officers  and 
members  are  devout  Catholics. 

The  shares  are  five  dollars  each,  and  may  be  paid  up  in. 
monthly  or  weekly  instalments.  A  member  has  but  one  vote 
regardless  of  the  number  of  shares  he  may  hold.  Withdraw- 
als may  be  made  practically  at  will,  and  there  is  very  little 
difference  between  the  paying  in  of  money  on  shares  and 
on  deposits.  A  month's  notice  is  all  that  is  required  of  a 
member  who  wishes  to  have  his  money  returned  on  his 
shares.  Dividends  are  distributed,  the  rate  ordinarily  being 
four  or  five  per  cent.  Since  the  shares  are  withdrawable,  the 
capital  of  the  bank  is  not  fixed,  as  in  a  joint-stock  company, 
but  is  variable  and  fluctuates  ia  size  as  members  come  in  and 
go  out.  Mr.  Desjardins  adopted  this  feature  because  he 
expected  that  his  bank  would  be  supported  and  used  by 
small  folk,  and  he  realized  that  this  class  is  unable  to  im- 
mobilize its  resources  and  would  perhaps  be  deterred  from 
joining  unless  it  had  the  privilege  of  regaining  possession  of 
them  if  desired.  As  he  says,  the  only  distinction  between  a 
share  and  a  deposit  is  that  the  former  is  made  up  of  savings 
with  a  view  of  meeting  future  contingencies  more  or  less  re- 
mote, while  the  latter  is  put  aside  for  almost  daily  use. 


448  EUEAL   CKEDITS 

Members  have  no  liability  except  for  the  amouiit  unpaid  on 
their  shares.  The  bank  has  protected  itself  against  possible 
losses  by  creating  a  reserve  into  ■which  at  least  ten  per  cent 
of  the  profits  are  placed  every  year.  In  case  of  dissolution 
this  reserve  would  not  be  distributed  among  the  members, 
but  would  be  used  for  some  work  of  public  utility  designated 
by  the  Lieutenant-Governor  of  the  Province  of  Quebec. 

The  management  of  the  bank  comprises  a  board  of  direc- 
tors, a  committee  on  credit,  and  a  board  of  supervision, 
elected  at  the  annual  meeting  of  the  members  from  among 
themselves.  Voting  by  proxy  is  not  allowed.  The  term  of 
office  is  so  arranged  that  a  certain  number  retire  annually. 
The  board  of  directors  consists  of  nine  members.  It  appoints 
one  of  its  members  to  be  president  and  general  manager,  and 
this  person  has  been  Mr.  Desjardins  since  the  foundation  of 
the  bank.  He  is  ex  officio  a  member  of  the  committee  on 
credit,  and  is  the  only  officer  allowed  to  be  on  two  of  these 
bodies  at  the  same  time.  Besides  having  generaL  charge  over 
the  affairs  of  the  bank,  the  board  of  directors  decides  upon 
the  admission  and  expulsion  of  members  and  acts  as  a  tri- 
bunal to  arbitrate  disputes  between  members  in  cases  pro- 
vided by  the  by-laws. 

The  board  of  supervision,  which  consists  of  three  mem- 
bers, is  the  most  important  body  in  the  bank  next  to  the 
shareholders  regularly  assembled.  Its  duties  are  indicated 
by  its  name.  It  must  examine  the  accounts  of  the  bank  and 
the  loan's  and  securities,  and  see  that  each  officer  conducts 
himself  properly.  It  may  even  suspend  an  officer,  but  in  that 
event  must  immediately  call  a  meeting  of  the  members 
finally  to  decide  upon  the  matter. 

The  committee  on  credit  consists  of  four  members.  Its 
sole  duty  is  to  pass  on  the  applications  for  loans  and  to  see 
that  repayments  are  promptly  made  or  good  reasons  given 
for  the  defaults.  No  loan  or  renewal  may  be  granted  unless 
all  members  of  the  committee  approve  it.  But  the  applica- 
tions are  not  addressed  directly  to  the  committee.  They 
must  be  submitted  to  the  president,  who  sends  them  up  to 
the  committee.     The  president,  being  the  manager,  is  the 


GEEAT  BRITAIN  AND  IRELAND,  ETC.     449 

most  active  ofiBcial  of  the  bank,  and  he  is  the  only  one  who 
receives  pay.  All  business  done  by  the  bank  with  the  mem- 
bers must  be  conducted  through  him,  subject  to  the  supervi- 
sion and  control  of  the  boards.  No  loans  may  be  made  except 
for  productive  or  provident  purposes.  Repayments  are  made 
by  instalments  if  a  loan  runs  for  a  year  or  longer,  and  the 
borrower  always  has  the  right  to  pay  in  advance.  Security 
in  the  form .  of  indorsement  by  one  or  two  other  members 
may  be  required.  The  interest  rate  on  loans  follows  the 
market,  whereas  at  Levis  in  the  days  before  the  Caisse  Popu- 
laire  existed  the  cruelist  kind  of  usury  was  practised  among 
the  classes  from  which  the  bank  recruits  its  members. 

There  is  no  Canadian  legislation  for  cooperative  associa- 
tions outside  of  Quebec.  The  law  in  that  province,  which 
was  enacted  in  1906,  incorporated  in  its  clauses  the  arrange- 
ment of  the  Levis  bank  as  to  organization  and  management, 
and  provides  that  an  association  for  supply  and  production 
as  well  as  credit  may  be  formed  by  13  persons  simply  by 
filing  articles  of  agreement  with  the  secretary-treasurer  of 
the  municipal  council  having  jurisdiction  over  the  place 
where  the  headquarters  are  located.  The  area  for  carrying 
on  operations  and  recruiting  members  is  limited  to  a  pro- 
vincial electoral  division,  except  that  in  cities  embracing 
more  than  one  such  division,  the  area  may  be  that  of  the 
entire  cities.  But  in  spite  of  this  restriction  an  association 
may  conduct  business  outside  of  its  territory  when  absolutely 
necessary  for  accomplishing  its  object  or  carrying  on  its 
affairs.  All  the  benefits  of  the  association  must  be  confined 
to  members.  Agricultural  societies,  agronomic  groups  and 
municipalities  are  able  to  become  members  of  an  association 
and  hold  shares  therein.  Honorary  members  and  officers  also 
may  be  admitted  but  can  take  no  part  in  the  management 
or  enjoy  any  of  its  benefits.  Shares  cannot  be  less  than  one 
dollar.  Holders  who  are  corporations,  municipalities  or  other 
associations  may  vote  by  proxy. 

The  shareholders  must  meet  at  least  once  a  year,  and  may 
proceed  to  do  business  no  matter  how  many  members  have 
responded  to  the  call,  since  no  size  may  be  set  for  a  quorum. 


450  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  board  of  directors  must  consist  of  at  least  five  mem- 
bers. The  by-laws  shall  prescribe  whether  they  are  renewed 
by  one-half  or  one-third  every  year.  They  choose  from 
among  themselves  a  president,  vice-president,  secretary  and 
manager,  who  act  as  such  for  the  association  during  the 
year.  The  board  meets  as  often  as  occasion  requires  upon 
call  of  the  president  or  of  two  of  its  members.  The  board  of 
supervision  must  consist  of  at  least  three  members,  and  the 
by-laws  may  prescribe  that  one  of  them  shall  be  renewed 
each  year.  The  board  has  the  power  to  convene  the  mem- 
bers in  special  session  whenever  it  deems  fit.  The  committee 
of  credit  must  be  composed  of  at  least  three  members,  and 
they  may  be  renewed  by  one-half  or  one-third  each  year. 
None  of  the  members  of  these  boards  or  the  committee  may 
borrow  directly  or  indirectly  from  the  association  or  indorse 
a  loan.  Every  association  should  aim  to  create  a  reserve. 
Ten  per  cent  of  the  profits  must  be  placed  in  the  reserve  until 
it  reaches  at  least  the  amount  of  the  liabilities.  When  this 
figure  has  been  attained  only  five  per  cent  need  be  devoted  to 
the  reserve,  but  this  latter  percentage  must  be  continued 
until  the  reserve  is  double  the  liabilities. 

All  the  cooperative  banks  in  Quebec  are  regulated  by  this 
law,  and  those  in  the  other  provinces  have  been  organized  and 
conduct  themselves  according  to  its  terms.  These  banks 
numbered  139  in  1913,  with  a  membership  of  65,700,  and 
had  assets  of  $1,945,000.  The  amount  of  the  loans  granted 
was  $3,560,800.  The  number  of  loans  was  between  14,000 
and  15,000,  showing  that  the  average  size  is  between  $237 
and  $250.  Over  $8,700,000  of  loans  has  been  accorded  since 
the  first  bank  was  started  14  years  ago,  not  one  cent  of  which 
has  been  lost.  No  bank  has  ever  even  made  a  loan  of  doubt- 
ful value. 

A  movement  for  cooperative  credit  has  now  become  gen- 
eral throiigh  Prench  Canada,  but  it  began  only  five  years 
ago.  The  delay  was  due  to  the  fact  that  Mr.  Desjardins,  who 
is  the  father  of  nearly  all  the  banks,  had  only  a  few  months 
to  give  to  the  work  each  year.  And  above  all  he  thought  it 
best  to  proceed  with  caution.     "We  wished,"  said  he,  "to 


GEEAT  BRITAIN  AND  lEELAND,   ETC.      451 

make  the  experiment  complete  and  conclusive  before  attempt- 
ing to  spread  this  new  idea.  So  during  eight  years  and  more, 
with  the  exception  of  two  cases,  where,  owing  to  proximity 
we  could  watch  the  operations  of  these  banks,  we  always 
refused  to  listen  to  the  requests  which  were  made  to  form 
banks  elsewhere,  replying  that  we  should  willingly  go  only 
after  experience  had  proved  that  our  plan  responded  to  a 
real  need  and  would  flourish  among  the  people."  This  hav- 
ing been  carefully  proved  by  eight  years  of  trial  at  Levis, 
Mr.  Desjardins  then  opened  an  active  campaign  of  propa- 
ganda, and  under  his  guidance  the  number  of  the  banks  has 
been  rapidly  increasing  during  the  past  three  years.  Eighty 
of  them  now  have  a  membership  composed  exclusively  of 
farmers. 

The  first,  and  so  far  the  only,  organized  effort  to  estab- 
lish cooperative  credit  among  farmers  in  the  United  States 
is  that  which  is  being  made  by  the  Jewish  Agricultural  and 
Industrial  Aid  Society,  a  benevolent  association  chartered  in 
1900  under  the  laws  of  the  State  of  New  York  to  take  over 
the  agricultural  branch  of  the  work  of  the  Baron  de  Hirsch 
Fund,  another  benevolent  association  chartered  in  1891  in 
the  same  state  to  administer  the  $3,400,000  donated  by  Baron 
Maurice  de  Hirsch  on  the  condition  that  its  income  should 
be  applied  to  assisting  Jewish  immigrants  driven  from  their 
homes  by  political  or  religious  persecutions.  These  two  as- 
sociations take  care  of  all  cases  of  destitution  which  appear 
to  need  their  help,  and  they  have  been  important  factors  in 
diverting  to  American  shores  the  refugees  from  the  periodi- 
cal pogroms  of  Eussia,  who  have  been  coming  in  such  large 
numbers  since  1889  that  today  the  United  States  has  a 
Jevidsh  population  second  only  to  that  of  Eussia  and  seems 
destined  to  have  the  greatest  in  the  world.  As  one  of  their 
leaders  says,  "this  country  presents  to  the  Jewish  emigrant 
better  opportunities  in  every  field  of  human  endeavor  than 
any  other  place  to  which  fate  has  directed  his  steps." 

The  Jewish  Agricultural  and  Industrial  Aid  Society  ob- 
tains the  money  for  its  operations  and  expenses  from  the 


452  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

Baron  de  Hirsch  Ftmd  and  the  Jewish  Colonization  Associa- 
tion, the  BarMi's  residuary  legatee.  In  1907  the  Society  elim- 
inated from  its  consideration  the  industrial  activities  of  immi- 
grants so  as  to  be  free  to  develop  entirely  along  agricultural 
lineSj  and  it  then  so  enlarged  its  scope  in  the  latter  respect 
as  to  become  the  head  of  the  propaganda  and  organization 
■work  for  Jewish  farmers,  immigrant  and  native,  throughout 
the  United  States.  This  change  of  policy  and  programme 
was  brought  about  by  Leonard  G.  Eobinson,  who  in  that  year 
was  appointed  the  general  manager  of  the  Society. 

Mr.  Eobiason,  himself  a  Eussian  immigrant,  is  a  gradu- 
ate of  Harvard  University  and  the  New  York  Law  School, 
an  education  secured  wholly  by  his  own  ambitions  and  un- 
remitting exertions.  la  his  control  the  Jewish  Agricultural 
and  Industrial  Aid  Society  gathered  strength  and  broadened 
its  purposes.  Moreover,  Mr.  Eobinson's  plan  of  action  was 
matured  when  he  assumed  the  duties  of  manager  of  the  So- 
ciety, since  he  had  been  identified  with  it  in  a  miaor  capacity 
for  the  previous  two  years  and  had  availed  himself  of  this 
opportunity  to  study  its  needs  and  possibilities.  One  of  the 
objects  specified  in  the  Society's  charter  was  to  encourage 
the  formation  of  cooperative  creameries,  factories  and  store- 
houses, and  this  gave  Mr.  Eobinson  his  cue.  In  his  reports 
of  1907  and  1909  he  called  the  attention  of  the  hoard  of 
directors  to  the  advisability  of  extending  cooperation  to 
credit. 

About  this  time  rural  cooperative  credit  was  ]ust  begia- 
ning  to  be  agitated  iu  the  United  States  and  the  first  indica- 
tions of  the  present  movement  were  making  their  appear- 
ance. But  while  the  movement  was  in  its  initiatory  stages, 
Mr.  Eobinson  actually  formed  rural  cooperative  banks  for 
the  members  of  the  Jewish  Agricultural  and  Industrial  Aid 
Society.  The  first  was  started  on  May  1,  1911,  at  Fair- 
field, Connecticut.  Two  others  were  started  in  the  same 
year,  five  more  in  1912,  and  by  the  end  of  1913  the  num- 
ber had  increased  to  18.  Owing  to  the  absence  of  coop- 
erative legislation  at  the  time,  these  banks  were  formed  sim- 
ply as  voluntary  associations.    In  organization  they  are  simi- 


GEEAT  BEITAIN  AND  IRELAND,  ETC.     453 

lar  to  the  Quebec  banks  of  Alphonse  Desjardins.  The  shares, 
five  dollars  each,  are  in  the  nature  of  certificates  of  deposit, 
payable  in  weekly  or  monthly  instalments,,  and  may  not  be 
issued  until  fully  paid  up.  They  impose  no  obligation  for 
compulsory  savings,  nor  are  they  intended  to  involve  the 
holder  in  unlimited  liability  for  the  debts  of  the  bank.  The 
share  has  no  voting  privilege.  This  attaches  to  membership 
alone,  and  no  member  may  have  more  than  one  vote  no 
matter  how  many  shares  he  may  hold.  Initiation  fees  may 
be  exacted  and  dividends  declared,  but  25  per  cent  of  the 
net  profits  must  be  written  to  the  reserve  each  year  until 
this  fund  equals  the  paid-in  capital. 

The  supreme  power  in  the  banks  rests  with  the  members 
regularly  assembled,  and  they  meet  at  least  once  a  year  to 
elect  officers  and  to  make  final  decisions  on  all  questions 
which  come  before  them.  The  administration  consists  of  a 
board  of  seven  directors  who  hold  office  for  one  year,  three 
of  their  places  becoming  vacant  and  being  refilled  each  year. 
The  president,  vice-president,  secretary,  treasurer,  and  the 
three  supervisors  constitute  this  board,  have  charge  of  all 
the  affairs  of  the  bank,  and  serve  as  the  credit  committee  to 
pass  on  applications  for  loans  and  attend  to  the  outstanding 
loans.  Mr.  Eobinson's  banks  do  not  separate  the  control, 
management  and  supervision  into  three  distinct  bodies  to  act 
as  checks  against  one  another  in  the  way  which  generally 
prevails  ia  European  cooperative  systems.  The  banks  do  not 
receive  deposits.  Their  business  is  confined  to  granting  loans 
to  members  for  amounts  and  terms  not  exceeding  $100  or 
six  months.  Every  loan  must  be  secured  by  the  promissory 
note  of  the  borrower  indorsed  by  one  or  more  responsible 
parties. 

The  members  of  the  banks  are  all  Jews,  and  as  a  rule 
are  also  members  of  some  other  Jewish  cooperative  or  social 
association  in  their  neighborhood,  which  are  banded  together 
into  the  Federation  of  Jewish  Farmers  of  America.  This 
body,  which  Mr.  Eobinson  plans  eventually  to  make  the  cen- 
tral organization  for  all  Jewish  farmers  in  America,  is  gov- 
erned by  officers  elected  by  the  adhering  associations  and 


454  EUEAL   CREDITS 

a  few  individual  members.  In  general  purpose  it  is  similar 
in  its  small  scope  to  the  Imperial  Federation  of  Germany, 
but  in  addition  it  maintains  a  purchasing  bureau  for  buying 
farm  equipment  and  supplies,  and  supports  itself  mainly  by  a 
small  percentage  added  to  the  wholesale  prices  at  which  it 
makes  sales  to  members  and  adherents. 

These  18  Jewish  banks  in  June,  1914,  had  a  total  mem- 
bership of  549 ;  the  smallest  had  21  members  and  the  largest 
48.  The  number  of  shares  issued  was  1,889,  of  a  face  value 
of  $9,445.  The  assets  aggregated  $29,488,  which  was  $1,887 
more  than  the  liabilities.  The  total  of  loans  granted  to  date 
was  $120,416  and  the  amount  outstanding  was  $27,036.  No 
losses  have  been  sustained  by  these  Jewish  banks.  Each 
bank  has  received  an  advance  at  two  per  cent  of  twice  its 
paid-up  capital  from  the  Jewish  Agricultural  and  Industrial 
Aid  Society.  The  number  of  members  belonging  to  these 
little  banks  appears  insigniiicant,  but  it  assumes  importance 
when  viewed  with  the  fact  that  there  are  only  3,718  Jewish 
families  living  on  farms  in  the  United  States.  This  means 
that  more  than  one  out  of  every  six  heads  of  families  is  a 
member  of  a  cooperative  credit  bank.  There  are  estimated 
to  be  18,590  souls  in  these  families,  a  mere  drop  when  com- 
pared with  the  entire  rural  population,  yet  they  are  the  fore- 
runners in  the  United  States  of  an  organized  agricultural 
cooperation  based  on  the  credit  society. 

There  were  Jews  in  America  when  New  York  was  a 
Dutch  possession.  A  Jew,  Abraham  de  Lyon,  introduced  silk 
and  vine  culture  into  Georgia  from  Portugal,  and  Major 
Manual  Noah,  the  famous  Jew  of  the  Eevolution,  appears  to 
have  been  the  first  to  attempt  to  establish  cooperative  farm 
colonies  in  the  United  States.  In  1820  Major  Noah  bought 
17,000  acres  on  Grand  Island  in  the  Niagara  Eiver,  and 
granted  allotments  to  a  group  of  his  coreligionists.  Nothing 
of  this  colony  remains  but  a  corner-stone.  In  1881,  60  Rus- 
sian Jewish  families  were  colonized  on  5,000  acres  on  Sicily 
Island,  Louisiana.  A  flood  swept  away  their  belongings  and 
they  dispersed.  In  1882  other  colonies  were  established  in 
a  number  of  states.     Twenty  families  were  located  in  what 


GEEAT  BEITAIN  AND  IRELAND,  ETC.     455 

is  now  Davison  County,  Sontli  Dakota.  The  Hessian  fly, 
droughts  and  haU  destroyed  their  crops  and  so  they  left. 
Thirteen  families  were  placed  on  government  land  in  Tre- 
mont  County,  Colorado.  Mountain  torrents  menaced  their 
lives  and  they  too  abandoned  their  colony.  A  tew  settlers 
gathered  in  Douglas  county,  Oregon,  but  stopped  farming  and 
took  to  selling  railway  ties ;  when  the  railroad  was  completed 
they  boarded  the  train  and  disappeared.  Seventy-two  fami- 
lies preempted  homesteads  in  Burleigh  County,  now  North 
Dakota.  Prairie  fires  and  bad  crops  caused  them  to  give  up 
the  struggle,  and  most  of  them  became  residents  of  Devil's 
Lake.  A  colony  in  Hodgeman  County,  Kansas,  and  three 
other  colonies  were  disbanded  in  1886. 

Of  all  the  colonies  founded  prior  to  1890,  only  the  colo- 
nies in  New  Jersey  survive,  and  they  are  industrial  as  much 
as  agricultural,  their  members  working  in  cooperative  shirt 
factories  and  cigar  factories.  The  colonies  more  recently 
established,  however,  are  distiactly  agrieidtural,  while  the 
groups  which  are  rapidly  supplanting  the  native  stock  in 
some  of  the  coTinties  lying  near  to  New  York  City  confine 
themselves  to  farming,  and  are  shovsdng  adaptability  to  agri- 
culture.    They  are  mostly  cooperative. 

In  1911  there  were  known  to  be  828  families  of  Jewish 
farmers  in  western  Canada,  most  of  whom  were  living  in 
cooperative  groups.  In  Argentina  a  Jewish  agricultural  col- 
ony was  founded  at  Bntre  Eios  in  1849  by  Baron  de  Hirsch. 
There  are  now  3,777  Jewish  families  on  farms  in  Argentina, 
and  50  families  in  Brazil.  The  number  of  Jewish  farmers 
in  all  Europe  west  of  Eussia  is  estimated  at  less  than  3,000. 


CHAPTEE  XXXII 

THE  PEINCIPLES   OF  COOPERATIVE   CEEDIT   AND   THEIE 
APPLICATION 

Spread  of  Cooperative  Credit  in  Europe  and  Asia. — ^Building  and 
Loan  Associations  and  Savings  Banks  in  the  United  States. — 
Mutual  and  Cooperative  Insurance. — No  Rural  Cooperative 
Credit  Systems  in  This  Country. — Characteristics  of  European 
System. — Two  Classes  of  Rural  Credit  Societies:  Limited  Lia- 
bility with  Shares  and  Unlimited  Liability  Paying  No  Divi- 
dends.— Simple  and  Uniform  Legislation  Desirable. — ^Function 
of  Cooperative  Systems  to  Ueceive  Deposits  and  Accord  Credit 
on  Security  Other  Than  Real  Estate. — Popular  Misconceptions 
as  to  European  Societies. — Advantages  of  a  Cooperative  Credit 
Society. — Credit  for  Members  and  Collective  Purchase  and  Sale. 
— Threefold  Structure  of  European  System. — ^Procedure  in 
Formation  of  a  Rural  Cooperative  Credit  Society. — The  Develop- 
ment.— ^Necessily  for  New  Laws  in  United  States. 

Although  cooperative  credit  without  real-estate  security 
has  been  implanted  in  all  European  countries  except  Norway, 
Denmark,  Luxemburg,  Monaco  and  Greece,  has  been  intro- 
duced into  Africa,  Asia,  America  and  some  island  colonies, 
and  is  now  being  agitated  for  agriculture  throughout  the 
civilized  world,  it  is  nevertheless  of  recent  growth  in  most 
countries,  and  has  attained  great  success  in  only  a  few.  No- 
where has  its  first  organization  been  due  to  the  farmers  or 
those  directly  benefited  by  it.  Its  original  organizer  in  each 
country  has  been  some  one  man  or  set  of  men  above  the 
necessity  of  borrowing  through  it  and  not  engaged  in  agri- 
culture. 

In  Germany  it  was  Sehulze-Delitzsch,  a  judge,  in  1850; 
in  Austria,  Ziller,  an  economist,  in  1858;  in  Belgium,  d'An- 
drimont,  an  economist,  in  1864;  in  Italy,  Luzzatti,  an  econo- 
mist, and  in  Eussia,  Louguinine,  a  priest,  in  1866;  in  Hun- 

456 


I^EINCIPLES  OF  COOPERATIVE  CREDIT    457 

gary.  Count  Karoiyi,  and  in  Switzerland,  Traber,  a  clergy- 
man, in  1887;  in  France,  Durand,  a  lawyer,  ia  1893;  in 
Bulgaria,  an  instructor,  and  in  Servia,  Aniramoviteh,  an 
economist,  in  1894;  in  Roumania,  the  state,  in  Holland,  the 
Catholic  clergy,  and  in  Ireland,  Sir  Horace  Plunkett,  in 
1895 ;  in  Canada,  Desjardins,  a  journalist,  in  1900 ;  in  Spain, 
■Gomez,  a  priest,  in  1901;  in  British  India,  the  state,  in 
1904;  in  the  United  States,  Desjardins  again,  in  1908;  in 
Japan,  the  state,  in  1909;  in  Egypt,  Lufty  Bey,  an  economist, 
in  1910.  In  every  other  country,  likewise,  it  was  some  pub- 
lic-spirited man  acting  singly  or  with  others  who  organized 
"the  first  cooperative  credit  society.  This  first  society  was 
not  agricidtural  in  all  cases.  As  a  rule  the  farmers  did  not 
Tise  cooperative  credit  until  the  city  folk  had  shown  the  way. 
The  countries  in  which  cooperative  credit  is  most  highly 
■developed  are  Germany,  Austria,  Belgium,  Russia  and  Italy, 
where  also  it  has  existed  the  longest.  It  has  made  substantial 
progress  among  farmers  in  Switzerland,  Japan  and  British 
India,  and  under  state  aid  in  France  and  Hungary.  In  the 
last  two  coimtries  the  credit  societies  do  not  attract  enough 
deposits  and  share  capital  for  their  operations,  nor  do  they 
obtain  many  loans  from  private  sources,  and  it  is  problemati- 
cal what  would  happen  if  the  aid  of  the  state  should  be  with- 
drawn. In  Servia,  Roumania  and  Bulgaria  recent  wars  have 
stopped  its  advance,  which  was  very  rapid  during  the  preced- 
ing decade  on  account  of  the  aid  and  intervention  of  the 
state.  The  annual  figures  of  the  number,  assets  and  mem- 
Taership  of  the  credit  societies  in  Germany  and  Austria  are 
very  large,  but  the  record  of  neither  of  them  equals  that  of 
-the  United  States  in  cooperative  finance  and  mutual  banking. 
In  1912  there  were  in  the  United  States  6,273  building  and 
loan  associations,  with  2,516,936  members  and  $1,137,600,- 
648  of  assets,  and  in  1913  more  than  623  mutual  savings 
banks,  with  8,101,238  depositors  and  $4,104,639,651  of  re- 
sources. The  building  and  loan  associations  are  organized 
for  thrift  and  a  specialized  kind  of  credit  based  on  urban 
real  estate,  and  the  mutual  savings  banks  for  thrift  and  for 
credit  not  necessarily  accorded  by  preference  to  members. 


458  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

In  neither  class  of  institution  is  credit  agricultural  or  so  dif- 
fused as  in  European  cooperative  systems;  nevertheless,  the 
figures  of  the  American  institutions  surpass  those  of  aU 
Schulze-Delitzseh  and  Luzzatti  banks  in  Europe  and  the 
German  landschafts  combined  in  respect  to  the  number  of 
persons  and  aggregate  of  wealth. 

In  making  this  comparison  between  numerical  strengths 
the  depositors  of  the  American  mutual  savings  banks  have 
aU  been  considered  as  members.  This  is  not  entirely  cor- 
rect, for  most  of  the  mutual  savings  banks  are  managed  by 
self-perpetuating  boards  of  trustees,  while  the  credit  they 
accord  does  not  go  by  preference  to  depositors.  The  same 
objections  may  be  raised,  however,  against  those  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  and  Luzzatti  banks  which  have  grovm  so  large  that 
all  members  do  not  exercise  their  voting  privileges.  There 
is  very  little  difference  in  spirit  and  business  methods  be- 
tween such  banks  and  the  American  mutual  savings  banks, 
since  in  both  the  granting  of  loans  to  members  is  second- 
ary to  the  encouragement  of  thrift,  the  accumulation  of 
deposits  and  the  safe  and  profitable  investment  of  assets. 
The  rise  of  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Luzzatti  banks  was 
due  to  the  fact  that  at  the  time  of  their  origin  there  were  in 
Europe  comparatively  few  privately  managed  banks  for  small 
savings.  Today  the  larger  portion  of  the  deposits  of  the 
plaia  people  in  Continental  countries  go  into  public  or  com- 
munal savings  banks  and  postal  savings  banks,  and  are  in- 
vested in  government  bonds  or  placed  in  the  possession  of 
the  government  so  that  the  state  may  have  control  of  them 
in  the  event  of  national  emergencies.  The  moving  purpose 
of  establishing  these  urban  cooperative  banks  often  has  been 
to  transfer  banking  from  public  or  semi-public  banks  into 
the  hands  of  the  people  and  to  give  them  the  management 
and  use  of  their  own  money.  An  element  of  social  and  po- 
litical reform  is  not  uncommon  in  European  cooperation. 
The  people's  banks"  of  the  Schulze-Delitzsch  and  Luzzatti 
types  in  a  measure  occupy  in  their  respective  countries  the 
place  held  in  the  United  States  by  the  mutual  savings  banks, 
the  medium-sized  national  banks  and  state-chartered  banks. 


PEINCIPLES   OP  COOPEEATIVE  CEEDIT    459 

Generally  speaking  they  are  not  small  credit  institutions  for 
feeble  folk.  Their  membership  is  recruited  from  the  same 
classes  of  people  as  belong  in  the  tJnited  States  to  the  build- 
ing and  loan  associations  and  the  savings  banks.  The 
American  enthusiasts  who  are  hoping  to  improve  the  condi- 
tion of  the  shifting  and  thriftless  population  by  means  of 
cooperation  wiU  be  disappointed  to  find  that  this  has  been 
accomplished  in  Europe  only  in  spots  where  the  work  is  sus- 
tained by  the  ceaseless  and  unrequited  toil  of  philanthropists 
devoting  themselves  to  the  arduous  tasks  as  priests  to  their 
mission. 

Besides  being  supreme  in  cooperative  fimance  and  mutual 
banking,  the  TJnited  States  outranks  the  world  also  in  mutual 
and  cooperative  insurance.  There  are  in  force  in  the  United 
States  close  to  $25,000,000,000  of  policies  in  such  insurance 
companies,  not  including  the  1,867  farmers'  mutual  insurance 
companies  of  various  kinds,  whose  numbers  are  rapidly  in- 
creasing in  the  upper  Mississippi  Valley.  The  New  York 
Life,  the  Mutual  Life,  the  New  England  Mutual  and  the 
Northwestern  Life  insurance  companies,  to  mention  only  a 
few  examples,  are  cooperative  except  for  the  one  point  that 
voting  may  be  done  by  proxy.  With  their  hundreds  of  thou- 
sands of  policyholders  and  hundreds  of  millions  of  assets 
they  are  not  only  the  greatest  cooperative  institutions  but  are 
also  among  the  greatest  and  soundest  and  in  actual  results 
the  most  benevolent  institutions  in  the  world.  The  figures 
for  insurance  alone  in  the  United  States  make  those  of  coop- 
eration and  mutuality  in  other  countries  appear  of  secondary 
importance.  The  cooperative  features  of  the  administration 
and  management  of  an  institution,  however,  invariably  be- 
come correspondingly  less  as  it  increases  in  size,  no  matter 
how  much  care  has  been  taken  in  making  the  organization 
perfectly  cooperative.  This  is  true  of  a  bank  or  of  any  other 
kind  of  concern.  The  majority  of  the  policyholders  of  the 
large  American  insurance  companies  do  not  exercise  their 
voting  privilege,  have  no  personal  acquaintance  with  their 
oflScers,  and  know  very  little  about  the  principles  of  insur- 
ance or  the  ways  in  which  their  funds  are  invested,  and  thus 


460  EURAL   CEEDITS 

through  the  lack  of  interest  of  the  policyholders  the  coopera- 
tive spirit  is  weakened.  This  does  not  mean  necessarily  that 
their  affairs  are  handled  any  the  worse  because  of  that  fact. 
It  simply  shows  that  undiluted  cooperation  cannot  be  prac- 
tised except  by  relatively  small  groups  of  persons. 

Mutual  telephone  companies  have  had  a  remarkable  de- 
velopment among  American  farmers  during  the  last  score 
of  years;  himdreds  of  them  are  now  in  existence.  American 
farmers  have  2,165  cooperative  creameries,  336  cooperative 
cheese  factories  and  2,026  cooperative  elevators  and  granar- 
ies, besides  many  fruit  growers'  associations  and  purchasing 
and  selling  agencies  organized  or  operated  on  a  cooperative 
plan.  The  progress  already  achieved  by  the  United  States 
in  mutual  and  cooperative  finance,  banking  and  insurance  in 
the  cities  and  in  rural  cooperation  for  insurance,  production 
and  distribution  is  frequently  overlooked,  but  it  has  a  bear- 
ing of  great  significance  on  the  question  of  rural  cooperative 
finance  because  it  proves  that  cooperation  and  mutuality  are 
congenial  to  the  spirit  of  the  American  people  and  may  be 
applied  in  their  most  complicated  forms  to  the  ordinary 
affairs  of  life. 

But  although  well  supplied  with  urban  institutions  for 
thrift  and  credit  and  with  great  numbers  of  rural  associa- 
tions of  the  kinds  mentioned,  the  United  States  has  nothing 
to  compare  with  the  rural  cooperative  credit  systems  which 
are  being  developed  in  Europe.  There  is  very  little  mixing 
in  Europe  of  urban  and  agricultural  business.  Each  class 
of  business  has  associations  of  its  own.  For  agriculture  these 
associations  are  parts  of  elaborately  organized  systems,  created 
in  either  of  two  ways.  Sometimes  the  farmers  belong  in  the 
first  instance  to  a  large  association  for  safeguarding  and  pro- 
moting their  general  interests,  and  as  members  of  this  large 
association  form  local  associations  for  industrial,  mercantile 
and  credit  purposes;  this  is  called  syndicalism  and  the  sys- 
tem prevails  in  France,  Belgium,  Portugal,  and  to  some  ex- 
tent, Holland.  Sometimes,  on  the  other  hand,  the  farmers 
acting  as  independent  individuals  first  form  the  local  asso- 


PRINCIPLES  OF  COOPERATIVE  CREDIT    461 

ciations,  whieh  in  their  turn  form  xmions  and  regional  asso- 
ciations out  of  which  are  formed  national  associations,  cor- 
porations and  federations;  this  process  of  building  up  from 
the  ground  is  called  decentralization,  because  it  leaves  to 
the  associations  in  each  union,  region  and  constituent  locality 
the  control  of  their  internal  affairs.  This  is  Germany's  sys- 
tem, although  the  Raiffeisen  associations  which  have  declared 
for  the  principle  have  not  yet  completed  their  transforma- 
tion. 

But  whatever  the  arrangement,  these  agricultural  coop- 
erative systems,  whether  aided  by  the  state  or  depending 
upon  self-help  alone,  have  the  credit  societies  for  their  basic 
units,  except  in  Denmark  and  Ireland.  In  Denmark  agri- 
culture is  highly  organized  cooperatively  but  mainly  for 
the  manufacture  and  marketing  of  milk  products.  The 
returns  from  these  with  middlemen  eliminated  are  quick 
and  profitable,  creating  a  large  volume  of  immediately  avail- 
able circulatory  capital  for  the  farmers.  Whatever  other 
funds  they  need  may  be  acquired  easily  by  loans  for  long 
or  short  time  from  the  excellent  Danish  land  mortgage  asso- 
ciations and  the  savings  and  ordinary  banks.  Consequently, 
as  there  is  no  need  for  cooperative  credit  societies,  none 
exists.  In  Ireland  also  the  majority  of  the  cooperative 
associations  are  dairies  and  creameries;  they  are  fairly  well 
served  by  the  ordinary  banks,  and  in  the  absence  of  a 
pressing  necessity  the  Irish  farmers  are  lax  in  their  efforts 
to  develop  cooperative  credit. 

The  main  characteristic  of  this  basic  unit  or  local  rural 
cooperative  credit  society  is  that  the  area  from  which  mem- 
bers are  recruited  is  so  restricted  that  all  members  or  at 
least  the  officers  may  know  personally  every  person  ad- 
mitted to  membership.  Indeed,  this  is  the  first  essential, 
for  not  otherwise  can  be  obtained  that  full  and  regular 
attendance  at  meetings  and  that  personal  acquaintanceship 
making  for  friendly  relations  and  mutual  confidence  which 
create  and  maintain  the  true  spirit  of  cooperation.  The 
number  of  members  rarely  exceeds  150,  while  frequently 
it  is  50  or  under.     Often  the  members  all  belong  to  the 


463  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

same  race,  religion  or  political  party,  and  thus  there  may 
be  several  societies  operating  mthin  the  same  area.  Indeed, 
it  is  best  for  the  society  to  impose  qualifications  for  mem- 
bership, since  the  resulting  homogeneity  assures  harmonious 
action.  It  matters  not  how  exclusive  the  local  societies  or 
the  unions  w^hich  they  form  may  be,  because  when  they 
connect  with  the  higher  organizations  which  look  after  the 
general  welfare  of  the  farmers  in  the  system  they  will 
reach  a  stage  where  there  is  complete  identity  of  interests 
among  all. 

The  rural  credit  society  is  not  an  aggregation  of  capital  but 
an  association  of  persons,  admitted  usually  upon  vote  of  the 
managers,  which  must  be  unanimous.  In  France,  members, 
individual  or  associational,  must  be  farmers  or  persons  en- 
gaged in  industries  or  vocations  connected  with  agricul- 
ture. In  Germany  this  requirement  is  not  imposed,  but  in 
every  country  members  must  be  residents  of  the  area  over 
which  the  society  in  which  they  apply  for  membership 
operates,  and  they  forfeit  membership  upon  moving  out  of 
that  area  or  upon  violating  any  of  the  conditions  set  forth 
in  the  by-laws.  Generally  a  member  must  subscribe  to  at 
least  one  share,  of  a  value  of  $10  more  or  less,  to  be  paid 
in  at  entrance  or  by  instalments  vnthia  one  or  two  years. 
In  the  German  Eaiffeisen  system  the  share  is  simply  a 
nominal  compliance  with  the  law,  siace  the  original  founder . 
did  not  believe  in  share  capital;  but  Eaiffeisen's  principles 
in  this  particular  are  now  allowable  by  law  and  practised 
only  by  the  rural  societies  in  Italy  and  a  few  other  coun- 
tries. Multiple  holdings  and  multiple  voting  up  to  a  cer- 
tain limit  are  permitted  in  some  countries,  but  as  a  ride  a 
member  is  entitled  to  only  one  vote,  to  be  exercised  in  per- 
son and  not  by  proxy,  no  matter  how  many  shares  he  may 
hold.  The  most  modern  laws  do  not  prescribe  a  limit  for 
dividends.  The  shares  in  effect  are  simply  certificates  of 
long-term  deposits  which  members  may  make  and  withdraw 
on  a  few  weeks'  notice,  and  the  societies  may  distribute 
among  them  all  the  annual  net  profits  after  setting  aside  a 
specified  portion  for  the  reserves.    It  may  be  said  that  the 


PRINCIPLES  OF  COOPEEATIVE   CEEDIT    463 

limitation  of  dividends  to  a  certain  annual  rate  exists  only 
in  state-aided  societies  or  in  those  whose  shares  are  of 
merely  nominal  value.  Societies  which  have  no  shares  of 
course  pay  no  dividends. 

The  presence  or  absence  of  shares  divides  the  rural  credit 
societies  into  two  classes.  Societies  with  shares  aU  are  on 
the  limited-liability  plan;  that  is,  in  the  event  of  their 
failure  a  member  may  lose  only  the  amount  paid  in  on  his 
shares  or  is  liable  to  pay  only  one  or  more  times  the  full 
face  value  of  his  shares  as  specified  in  the  by-laws.  In 
societies  without  shares  or  in  which  the  shares  have  only  a 
nominal  value,  the  liability  is  unlimited;  that  is,  the  mem- 
bers are  jointly  and  severally  liable  for  all  obligations  in- 
curred by  their  societies,  and  this  liability  may  be  enforced 
by  a  society's  creditor  against  any  member  whom  he  may 
choose  to  sue,  or  else  it  is  enforceable  in  bankruptcy  by 
assessments  equal  on  all  members  continued  until  the  close 
of  the  proceedings.  Members  of  an  unlimited-liability  society 
who  have  been  compelled  to  pay  more  of  its  debts  than 
their  just  portions  have  a  right  of  recovery  for  the  excess 
against  fellow  members  whose  assessments  have  not  been  col- 
lected. There  is  another  difference  of  vital  importance: 
The  unlimited-liability  society  having  no  shares  naturally 
pays  no  dividends;  all  the  profits  belong  to  the  society  and 
not  to  the  individual  members  and  are  placed  in  the  re- 
serve; hence  the  reserve  rapidly  increases  in  size  in  a  sue 
cessful  society  and  serves  not  only  as  a  guaranty  fund  but  also 
as  a  working  fund.  In  both  classes  of  societies  the  reserve  is 
indivisible;  that  is,  in  the  event  of  dissolution  it  is  not 
distributed  among  members  but  is  used  for  forming  a  new 
credit  society  in  the  same  locality  or  is  devoted  to  some 
agricultural  object  of  general  benefit  to  the  system. 

The  rural  credit  societies  are  financed  by  surpluses  and 
reserves,  by  deposits  received  from  members  and  outsiders, 
by  money  borrowed  on  the  collective  liability  of  members,  by 
small  admission  fees  (except  in  the  German  Eaiffeisen  so- 
cieties), and  by  share  capital  in  societies  which  issue  shares. 
Its  variability  due  to  payments  and  withdrawal  on  shares 


464  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

■vroiild  make  such  a  capital  an  unreliable  fund  for  steady 
operations  if  it  stood  alone;  consequently  the  societies  are 
required  to  reinforce  it  by  raising  the  reserves  to  a  sub- 
stantial figure.  By  the  French  law  three-fourths  of  the 
net  profits  must  be  written  each  year  to  the  reserve  until  it 
equals  one-half  of  the  capital;  in  Germany  the  by-laws  of 
each  society  must  prescribe  the  ratio  at  which  the  one  fund 
must  be  maintained  to  the  other.  The  societies  do  not  enjoy 
many  special  privileges.  The  few  which  are  accorded,  how- 
ever, are  important,  comprising  tax  exemptions  for  deposits 
and  freedom  from  or  reduction  of  stamp  duties  and  fees, 
60  that  the  bills  of  exchange  and  other  negotiable  instru- 
ments, usually  for  small  sums,  may  be  executed,  accepted  or 
discounted  at  less  expense  than  is  connected  with  such  trans- 
actions by  ordinary  banks. 

In  aU  European  countries  there  is  a  marked  similarity 
in  the  administration  of  cooperative  credit  societies.  The 
supreme  authority  within  the  society  is  lodged  in  the  mem- 
bers regularly  assembled.  By  a  majority  vote  they  may 
set  aside  any  act  of  the  ofiBcers  and  exercise  directly  all 
powers  of  the  society,  and  by  a  larger  vote,  usually  three- 
fourths,  they  may  dismiss  oflScers,  amend  the  by-laws  or  dis- 
solve the  society.  AU  officers  are  elected  by  the  members. 
As  a  rule  the  committee  of  management  is  composed  of 
three  members,  one  of  whom  is  retired  or  reelected  each  year. 
One  of  the  managers  is  designated  as  chairman  or  president. 
Separate  and  distinct  from  this  body  is  a  board  of  three 
supervisors  elected  in  the  same  way.  Their  duties  are  to 
keep  vigilant  watch  over  the  society's  affairs  and  to  oversee 
and  inspect  the  work  of  the  managers ;  they  may  veto  the  act 
of  any  oflBcer  or  employee  and  even  suspend  him  until  the 
matter  is  brought  before  a  meeting  of  the  members.  The 
compensation  of  the  managers  and  supervisors  is  always 
small  and  in  some  cases  they  receive  none,  while  they  are 
excluded  from  the  credit  facilities  of  the  society  and  from 
serving  as  sureties  for  other  borrowers,  except  upon  per- 
mission granted  at  a  meeting  of  the  members.  The  secre- 
tary-treasurer is  not  considered  as  an  ofiBcial;  he  is  a  paid 


PEINCIPLES  OF  COOPERATIVB  CEBDIT    465 

employee  chosen  by  the  managers  and  supervisors.  Usually 
he  must  enroll  himself  as  a  member  upon  appointment. 

Besides  these  officials  and  employees  an  auditor  is  ap- 
pointed by  the  court  or  by  the  union  or  federation  of  the 
system  to  which  the  society  belongs.  If  appointed  by  a  union, 
he  is  invariably  a  trained  and  experienced  expert,  and  in 
addition  to  his  ordinary  functions,  he  acts  as  adviser  to 
protect  the  society  from  bad  business  practices  and  from 
deviating  from  strict  cooperative  principles.  Each  society 
is  inspected  by  an  auditor  at  least  once  every  two  years. 
Certified  copies  of  the  annual  reports  checked  by  the  auditor 
must  be  filed  in  a  special  registry  in  the  district  court  and 
published  in  the  official  newspaper.  The  articles  of  agree- 
ment must  be  filed  and  published  in  a  like  manner,  and 
a  list  of  members,  showing  the  shares,  if  any,  held  by  each, 
must  be  kept  up  to  date  in  the  registry.  Every  member 
must  declare  in  writing  his  adherence  to  these  articles  in 
a  declaration  which  is  a  separate  paper  from  the  subscrip- 
tion for  shares.  This  outside  audit  and  the  official  regis- 
tration and  publication  enable  all  who  deal  with  a  society 
easily  to  obtain  correct  and  exact  information  of  its  af- 
fairs. They  have  been  the  greatest  factors  in  maintaining 
the  solvency  of  the  cooperative  systems  of  Europe. 

The  best  legislation  does  not  comprise  one  law  for  credit 
societies  and  another  for  societies  for  other  cooperative  pur- 
poses, but  consists  of  one  omnibus  act  governing  coopera- 
tive societies  of  all  kinds.  No  matter  whether  the  socie- 
ties are  mercantile,  industrial  or  financial,  or  whether  they 
are  organized  on  a  limited-  or  imlimited-liability  basis 
with  or  without  shares,  the  legal  requirements  relating  to 
the  administration  and  management  are  the  same,  and  a 
farmer  who  joins  any  of  them  knows  just  how  to  act  and 
what  to  expect.  There  is  no  need  for  the  states  of  the 
United  States  to  enact  special  legislation  for  credit  socie- 
ties. If  each  state  had  a  single  law  on  cooperation,  embrac- 
ing societies  extending  credit  not  based  on  real  estate,  the 
organization,  administration,  management  and  business 
methods  of  cooperative  societies  for  all  objects  and  of  all 


466  EUEAL    CEEDITS 

classes  would  become  standardized  in  the  state,  and  the 
farmers,  saved  from  the  necessity  of  studying  complex  laws, 
eventually  would  leam  how  to  apply  cooperation  to  all  their 
activities  in  accordance  with  simple  and  well  known  statu- 
tory regulations.  Cooperation  cannot  progress  easily  and 
rapidly  unless  these  regulations  are  simplified  and  stand- 
ardized. The  farmers  must  be  brought  to  understand  that 
the  transactions  of  a  credit  society  are  in  fact  less  com- 
plicated than  those  of  any  other  kind  of  cooperative  society. 
In  all  cooperative  systems  not  aided  by  the  state  the 
first  two  functions  of  a  credit  society  are  the  reception  of 
deposits  from  members  and  outsiders  and  the  according  of 
credit  to  members  on  security  not  based  on  real  estate.  In 
Canada  credit  societies  do  not  accept  deposits  from  out- 
siders, but  there  is  no  good  reason  for  this  limitation  since 
deposits  from  the  outside,  being  in  effect  borrowed  money 
subject  to  call  at  will  or  on  short  notice,  constitute  the 
greatest  source  of  capital.  In  agricultural  societies  the 
stimulation  of  thrift  is  not  to  the  same  extent  as  in  urban 
societies  the  purpose  of  attracting  deposits.  Indeed,  this 
purpose  is  incidental,  for  the  prime  reason  clearly  is  that 
deposits  are  the  easiest  way  to  raise  funds  for  financing 
members  in  their  various  undertakings.  The  agricultural 
credit  societies  are  far  from  being  mere  benevolent  institu- 
tions for  helping  poor  and  feeble  folk  or  from  being  train- 
ing schools  for  persons  not  possessing  industrious,  econom- 
ical and  orderly  habits.  They  are,  it  is  true,  about  the 
only  means  through  which  such  classes  can  be  permanently 
benefited  and  improved;  nevertheless  the  substantial  farm- 
ers preponderate  in  the  membership  in  the  places  where  the 
societies  are  the  most  numerous  and  successful. 

A  great  deal  of  misinformation  on  European  cooperation 
has  crept  into  the  United  States.  The  societies,  it  has  been 
asserted  again  and  again,  grant  cheap  and  easy  credit,  at 
interest  far  below  current  rates,  down  to  three  and  even 
two  per  cent,  upon  character  alone.  No  statement  could  be 
farther  from  the  truth.     Only  in  Italy  is  character  credit 


PEINCIPLES  OF  COOPEEATIVB   CKEDIT    467 

ever  accorded,  and  there,  too,  only  now  and  then  by  Luz- 
zatti's  urban  banks  in  the  form  of  'Tionor  loans"  to  indigent 
persons  out  of  a  small  portion  of  their  profits  which  they 
can  afford  to  lose  set  aside  each  year  as  a  pure  act  of 
charity.  With  this  small  exception  there  is  no  cooperative 
credit  society  in  Europe  which  does  not  demand  of  bor- 
rowers as  safe  security  as  is  exacted  by  an  ordinary  bank. 
Moreover,  interest  rates  are  never  below  those  on  sound 
and  marketable  securities  except  where  the  state  has  ad- 
vanced public  fimds  to  be  distributed  in  free  or  cheap  loans. 
Again,  there  is  a  mistaken  notion  that  a  Hmit  must  be 
set  to  the  rate  of  interest  and  also  of  dividends.  The 
state  of  course  designates  the  interest  rate  at  which  the 
moneys  it  advances  shall  be  loaned  and  invariably  stipu- 
lates that  the  societies  it  selects  for  the  distribution  shall 
not,  if  they  have  shares,  pay  more  than  a  certain  per  cent 
in  dividends.  This  is  done  to  prevent  the  society  from 
making  profits  at  the  expense  of  the  state's  intended  bene- 
ficiaries. Occasionally  also  societies  not  aided  by  the  state 
limit  dividends,  but  never  on  account  of  any  antipathy  to 
money.  When  this  is  done  it  is  for  the  purpose  of  shifting 
money  obtainable  from  shares  over  to  deposits  and  thereby 
establishing  a  fair  balance  between  the  shareholding  and 
the  borrowing  members,  particularly  in  societies  where 
multiple  voting  is  allowed.  Ordinarily  the  societies  may 
charge  interest  on  loans  as  high  as  that  allowed  by  the 
usury  laws  but  in  fact  they  never  touch  that  limit. 

The  nearest  the  societies  come  to  extending  credit  on 
character  is  when  they  permit  a  member  to  draw  against 
an  uncovered  open  account  up  to  an  agreed  amount.  Only 
those  members  who  have  unencumbered  and  readily  attach- 
able property,  however,  are  allowed  this  privilege,  while 
the  agreed  amount  of  the  account  is  fixed  at  considerably 
less  than  the  ascertained  value  of  their  property.  Chattel 
mortgages  and  pledges  of  personal  property  are  not  un- 
common, while  the  credit  societies  have  been  tempted  even 
to  assist  members  to  acquire  small  holdings  on  real-estate 
mortgages  and  have  invested  their  surpluses  in  such  secur- 


468  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

ities.  Serious  consequences  have  resulted  from  this  prac- 
tice. The  entire  rural  cooperative  system  of  the  Grand 
Duchy  of  Hesse  has  been  shaken  to  its  foundation  by  thus 
tying  up  funds  of  the  credit  societies,  but  bitter  experience 
is  gradually  teaching  cooperatives  to  let  real-estate  mort- 
gages alone.  The  preferred  security  is  the  indorsement  of 
one  or  more  responsible  parties,  and  with  the  rare  exceptions 
noted,  the  societies  wUl  not  extend  credit  on  anything  less. 
The  societies  themselves  are  able  to  borrovr  upon  no  other 
security  than  the  collective  liability  of  their  members,  and 
this  is  what  is  meant  in  speaking  of  the  character  credit 
which  is  available  for  cooperatives. 

The  interest  rate  for  loans,  discounts  and  acceptances  by 
European  rural  cooperative  credit  societies  after  they  have 
been  firmly  established  is  never  more  than  that  charged 
inerehants  by  the  ordinary  banks  in  their  locality,  while  in 
fth&  German  Eaiffeisen  societies  it  may  be  less  than  the  com- 
mercial rate,  for  a  reason  already  explained.  The  American 
farmers  should  disabuse  their  minds  of  the  stories  recently 
told  them  of  the  fabulously  cheap  money  in  the  European 
credit  societies.  There  is  enough  good  in  cooperation  to 
assure  its  spread,  when  once  it  becomes  understood,  through- 
out the  United  States  without  the  invention  of  fictitious  ad- 
vantages. The  granting  of  agricultural  credit  is  expensive 
to  the  ordinary  lender  because  of  the  costs  of  examining 
the  securities  offered  and  of  making  recoveries  and  is  not 
profitable  unless  it  yields  an  interest  rate  sufficiently  high  to 
cover  all  costs  and  risks.  Furthermore,  it  is  objectionable 
because  of  the  slowness  of  repayment,  and  the  farmer  finds 
himself  paying  renewal  fees,  commissions  and  bonuses  in 
addition  to  the  written  rate,  to  say  nothing  of  his  feeling 
more  like  a  beggar  for  favors  than  a  claimant  of  rights 
when  the  period  of  the  loan  expires.  Consequently  he 
avoids  the  money  lenders  and  the  banks  as  much  as  pos- 
sible, and  too  often  he  buys  his  implements  and  supplies 
on  time,  without  knowing  what  the  merchant  is  charging 
him  for  deferred  payment,  and  lets  his  account  at  the 
country  store  run  indefinitely  to  be  settled  finally  by  turn- 


PEINCIPLES-  OP  COOPEEATIVE  CEEDIT    469 

ing  over  produce  at  the  storekeeper's  price.  When  the 
farmer  cannot  get  along  any  longer  in  this  fashion,  he 
raises  money  for  his  debts  by  placing  a  three-  or  five-year 
mortgage  on  his  homestead  with  little  hope  of  paying  it  ofE 
within  that  time.  If  a  crash  comes  he  blames  the  monetary 
system  and  the  capitalists. 

All  these  bad  practices  and  troubles  would  disappear 
if  cooperation  were  introduced.  There  would  be  no  more 
commissions  and  bonuses  or  difficulty  in  getting  renewals 
or  new  loans,  while  the  interest  rate  would  drop  eventually 
to  a  figure  as  low  as  that  at  which  the  most  solvent  man 
in  the  nearest  city  could  obtaia  credit.  The  farmer  should 
not  expect  the  rate  to  fall  below  that  figure  because  the 
money  lent  to  him  comes  from  the  deposits  and  share  pay- 
ments of  his  neighbors  or  was  borrowed  on  their  collective 
liability  as  fellow  members,  all  of  which  must  be  repaid 
and  remunerated  at  reasonable  interest  rates.  However, 
the  rural  cooperative  credit  society  does  not  pay  big  sal- 
aries or  dividends  to  outsiders,  while  it  saves  expenses  by 
being  situated  in  the  locality  in  which  it  transacts  business, 
so  its  outlays  are  small,  and  this  inures  to  the  benefit  of 
its  borrowers. 

But  borrowers  are  not  the  only  persons  in  a  cooperative 
credit  society,  nor  are  the  reduction  of  interest  and  easy 
terms  on  loans  the  only  advantages  which  it  affords.  The 
belief  prevailing  in  the  United  States  that  a  rural  coop- 
erative credit  society  is  an  association  composed  entirely 
of  borrowers  or  of  persons  expecting  to  become  borrowers 
is  true  only  for  the  state-aided  systems  of  France  and 
Hungary,  which  small  farmers  join  in  order  to  obtain  cheap 
loans  from  the  free  money  supplied  by  the  governments. 
The  French  or  Hungarian  farmer  gives  but  slight  atten- 
tion to  his  society  when  once  he  has  received  his  loan  from 
the  Government;  he  makes  no  deposits  and  buys  no  shares 
if  he  can  escape  doing  so,  and  leaves  the  future  to  the 
next  farmer  who  may  want  a  lift  from  the  Government. 
In  Germany,  however,  where  the  systems  were  created  and 
are  maintained  and  managed   by  the  farmers   themselves 


470  KUEAL   CEEDITS 

and  where  in  consequence  of  that  fact  agricultural  coop- 
eration has  been  the  most  highly  developed,  the  farmer 
when  he  joins  a  credit  society  joins  to  stay,  becomes  an 
active  member,  considers  himself  honored  if  elected  one 
of  its  officers,  uses  it  as  a  depositary  for  all  his  savings 
and  disposable  cash,  and  resorts  to  it  for  facilitating  his 
financial  transactions  of  all  kinds. 

In  Germany  the  rural  cooperative  credit  society  is  far 
from  being  a  mere  thrift-stimulating  and  money-lending  in- 
stitution. It  is  not  only  unexcelled  in  these  two  capacities, 
but  it  also  renders  banking  services  of  every  description  to 
its  members.  Small  though  it  may  be,  it  is  one  of  many 
thousands  of  similar  basic  units  which  form  or  help  to  sus- 
tain a  mighty  system  of  local,  regional  and  national  coop- 
erative banks,  factories,  supply  stores,  and  selling  and  mar- 
keting agencies,  aU  bound*  together  and  guided  by  unions, 
provincial  federations  and  national  federations  organized  for 
subserving,  protecting  and  promoting  the  various  interests 
of  agriculture.  Most  of  the  money  for  carrying  on  the 
business  of  this  system  comes  out  of  the  local  cooperative 
credit  societies  and  into  them  again  finally  flow  the  profits 
distributed  among  the-  farmers.  The  transactions  between 
individuals  of  the  same  neighborhood,  between  societies  and 
the  regional  banks,  between  the  regional  banks  and  the 
central  and  national  institutions,  and  between  the  latter 
and  the  outside  world  are  represented  by  negotiable  instru- 
ments and  bankable  paper  which  pass  back  and  forth  through 
these  channels  with  the  movement  of  trade,  the  purchase 
of  supplies,  the  sale  of  produce  and  commodities,  and  aU 
the  exigencies  calling  for  the  transfer  of  money  from  one 
place  to  another.  The  advantages  gained  from  this  inter- 
relation and  united  action  among  the  farmers  of  Germany 
are  so  great  that  the  local  cooperative  credit  societies  would 
continue  to  exist  even  if  they  did  not  have  a  borrowing 
member.  Indeed,  the  richer  the  members  become,  and  they 
have  become  richer,  and  the  less  need  they  have  of  credit 
except  for  the  requirements  of  trade  and  commerce,  the 
larger  and  more  powerful  the  system  itself  becomes  through 


PEINCIPLES  OF  COOPEKATIVE  CEEDIT    471 

the  increase  in  the  number,  membership  and  resources  of 
these  now  indispensable  financial  and  banking  xm.its  in 
agricultural  Germany. 

The  power,  elasticity  and  solidity  of  the  two  German 
rural  cooperative  credit  systems  are  a  striking  and  com- 
plete proof  of  the  wonderful  value  and  effectiveness  of  co- 
operation for  farmers.  They  have  spread  over  the  larger 
portion  of  the  Empire  without  weakening  their  framework 
at  any  point.  Although  somewhat  artificially  and  faultily 
built  at  the  top  and  open  to  domination  by  ambitious 
leaders,  they  have  recovered  from  financial  depressions, 
faults  of  management  and  even  the  shock  of  war  with  a 
resilience  possible  only  for  the  strongest  institutions,  and  no 
doubt  is  now  ever  raised  as  to  the  integrity  or  ability  of 
their  components  to  perform  any  engagement  they  under- 
take. Yet  these  systems  are  based  on  small  local  credit  so- 
cieties, each  apparently  so  insignificant  that  its  only  out- 
ward and  visible  sign  is  a  desk  and  strongbox  in  a  room 
in  some  farm  home  or  country  school.  This  unit  owes  no 
allegiance  which  it  cannot  dissever  at  wiU,  and  its  own 
members  also  may  retire  and  withdraw  their  deposits  and 
shares  or  even  dissolve  the  society  practically  at  will,  for 
it  is  merely  a  club  of  a  few  friendly  neighbors  associated 
under  statutory  formalities  of  rural  simplicity. 

Such  an  easily  formed  and  easily  dissolved  little  asso- 
ciation as  this  may  not  appear  fit  to  serve  as  the  basic 
imit  in  a  great  financial,  commercial  and  industrial  sys- 
tem. N^evertheless,  in  Germany  it  attracts  deposits  as  read- 
ily as  a  savings  bank  or  a  postal  savings  bank,  remits  what 
it  does  not  need  to  other  societies,  draws  against  their  sur- 
pluses to  supply  its  own  deficiencies,  and  borrows  when 
necessary  from  outside  banks  or  money  lenders  at  the  lowest 
current  interest  rates  for  making  loans  to  members  or  ad- 
vancing funds  to  other  societies  and  higher  organizations 
in  the  system.  Thus  its  influence  and  relations  may  extend 
beyond  its  immediate  neighborhood  to  the  farthest  parts  of 
the  Empire.  As  a  rule  the  German  rural  cooperative  credit 
societies  have  no  trouble  in  finding  all  the  money  they  need. 


473  EURAL   CEEDITS 

because  the  collective  liability  of  their  members,  standing 
all  for  one  and  each  for  all,  has  been  proved  by  the  test  of 
years  to  be  a  security  equal  to  the  best.  Most  of  the  money 
comes  from  members,  however,  and  naturally  so  because 
most  of  the  rural  producers  become  members. 

In  coimtries  where  the  farmers  apply  cooperation  not 
only  to  credit  and  banking  but  also  to  industrial,  mercan- 
tile, commercial  and  all  other  activities,  the  rural  coopera- 
tive credit  society  has  two  general  uses  for  its  funds.  The 
first  is  to  extend  credit  to  members,  and  the  second,  to 
finance  undertakings  for  collective  purchase,  collective 
sales  and  the  manufacture  in  common  of  marketable  com- 
modities out  of  farm  produce.  The  credit  accorded  to  mem- 
bers consists  mainly  of  three-months  loans  renewable  three 
or  four  times  if  necessary.  If  loans  for  over  a  year  are 
granted  they  are  repayable  in  instalments  and  recallable  by 
the  society  on  a  few  weeks'  notice.  The  most  usual  method 
of  financing  the  undertakings  just  referred  to  is  by  buying 
shares  or  bonds  of  other  cooperative  associations  organized 
for  such  special  purposes.  Generally  the  rural  cooperative 
credit  society  and  its  individual  members  acquire  shares 
in  these  other  local  associations,  then  these  associations  and 
the  rural  cooperative  credit  society  acquire  shares  in  the 
regional  banks  and  regional  associations,  and  so  on  up  to 
the  top.     Thus  all  are  welded  into  a  united  system. 

The  profits  realized  in  the  system  are  distributed  as 
dividends  by  the  higher  institutions  to  the  local  associations 
and  finally  reach  the  farmers  through  their  local  credit 
societies.  If  the  local  society  has  shares,  it  also  distributes 
dividends;  if  it  does  not  have  shares,  the  gains  which  fall 
to  it  all  go  into  the  reserves,  gradually  giving  it  more  funds 
of  its  own  to  lend  to  members.  By  being  thus  relieved  more 
and  more  from  the  necessity  of  borrowing  on  its  own  part, 
the  rural  cooperative  credit  society  is  able  as  time  pro- 
gresses to  charge  lower  interest  rates  or  pay  larger  dividends 
to  members.  The  savings  resulting  from  the  buying  of 
supplies  at  wholesale  prices,  the  marketing  of  produce  and 
the  manufacture  and  distribution  of  commodities  without 


PEINCIPLES   OF  COOPERATIVE   CEEDIT    473 

the  interyention  of  middlemen  and  outside  merchants  are 
advantages  which  the  societies  directly  or  indirectly  afford 
and  are  indeed  of  greater  value  to  members  in  general  than 
cheap  and  easy  credit.  All  the  German  Eaiffeisen  credit 
societies  and  many  of  the  other  rural  credit  societies,  instead 
of  forming  other  local  associations  to  exist  alongside  of  them, 
have  trading  and  banking  as  their  dual  function,  and  make 
collective  purchases  for  their  members  and  sometimes  col- 
lective sales.  Locally  this  has  proved  to  be  the  best  ar- 
rangement, since  it  centers  the  various  activities  of  the  local 
group  in  one  society  under  one  set  of  oflScers  and  employees, 
thus  saving  expense  and  making  an  arrangement  more  con- 
venient for  members.  The  supplies  bought  by  a  member 
are  either  charged  against  his  account  or  else  are  sold  to 
him  on  time  evidenced  by  a  promissory  note ;  there  are  book- 
keeping and  papers  for  only  one  transaction  instead  of  for 
two  transactions  as  would  have  been  the  case  if  the  business 
had  been  done  by  separate  associations. 

The  European  agricultural  cooperative  systems  which 
embrace  banking  all  have  the  same  kind  of  structure  and 
scheme  of  arrangement.  Eirst  the  farmers  are  organized 
locally  by  belonging  to  credit  societies  having  the  dual  func- 
tion of  banking  and  trading,  or  else  they  belong  to  credit 
societies  and  also  to  other  local  associations  connected  with 
the  credit  societies.  These  groups  of  local  societies  and  asso- 
ciations form  regional  banks  and  associations  and  all  are 
bound  together  in  what  are  called  unions.  The  unions, 
known  as  syndicats  in  France  and  other  Latin  countries,  are 
the  second  degree  of  organization  in  the  system,  and  they 
are  the  most  important  factors  in  extending  and  preserv- 
ing it. 

In  some  instances  the  unions  do  collective  purchasing, 
but  the  approved  practice  is  to  keep  the  union  free  of 
business  affairs,  so  that  it  may  be  devoted  to  its  chief  and 
especial  purposes  of  supervision,  inspection,  auditing,  propa- 
gandism,  the  encouragement  of  the  formation  of  new  credit 
societies  and  associations  for  other  cooperative  purposes, 
and  the  defense  and  promotion  of  the  general  interests  of  the 


474  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

organized  farmers  within  its  region.  The  societies  and  asso- 
ciations of  the  region  create  regional  banks  and  associa- 
tions with  headquarters  at  the  place  where  the  union  has 
its  headquarters,  which  are  often  managed  by  officers  of  the 
union.  The  officers  of  the  regional  banks  and  associations 
and  of  the  unions,  elected  by  the  adhering  local  societies  and 
associations,  are  drawn  from  among  the  most  substantial  and 
prominent  farmers  of  the  region  and  from  the  priests, 
preachers,  bankers,  large  landowners,  and  influential  busi- 
ness men  identified  with  agriculture  who  not  infrequently 
are  allowed  to  join  the  local  cooperative  credit  societies  to 
give  them  standing. 

The  third  and  final  degree  of  organization  in  the  sys- 
tem comprises  the  federations  created  for  linking  the  imions 
together,  for  bringing  about  the  formation  of  central  asso- 
ciations and  banks,  and  for  directing  and  enlarging  the 
system  in  its  national  scope.  The  two  German  agricul- 
tural cooperative  systems  are  the  only  ones  in  Europe  which 
are  extensively  developed  in  the  third  degree  of  organization, 
and  these  two  systems  are  the  results  of  many  years  of 
slow  upward  growth.  Such  an  elaborate  system  cannot 
have  a  rapid  growth  if  it  is  expected  to  be  sound  and 
enduring.  It  is  doubtful  whether  outsiders,  even  with  the 
aid  of  the  state,  could  create  one  by  beginning  at  the  top 
and  working  down.  If  the  farmers  of  the  United  States 
wish  such  a  system,  it  is  in  their  power  to  start  it  them- 
selves at  the  grass  roots  by  forming  small  local  cooperative 
credit  societies.  If  they  are  not  hasty  in  action  or  over- 
ambitious,  in  due  course  of  time  by  gradual  steps  they  will 
become  firmly  organized  in  local  groups,  in  regional  groups 
or  unions,  and  in  federations  with  local,  regional  and  central 
associations  and  institutions  for  finance  and  all  their  other 
needs  and  necessities. 

A  rural  cooperative  credit  society  is  the  easiest  kind  of 
an  association  to  form  and  operate.  As  one  illustration 
of  many  that  might  be  used,  let  us  assume  that  there  are  50 
farmers  living  along  a  five-mile  stretch  of  road  leading  out 


PEIISrCIPLES   OF  COOPEEATIVE   CEEDIT    475 

from  a  town  in  an  agricultural  region.  They  meet  at  the 
district  school,  church  or  some  convenient  farmhouse,  and 
form,  not  a  corporation,  but  rather  a  club,  and  elect  from 
among  themselves  two  men  to  act  as  managers  and  three 
as  supervisors  and  another  to  serve  as  secretary-treasurer. 
The  secretary-treasurer  man  lives  at  the  end  of  the  road 
farthest  from  town,  and  every  Saturday  morning  he  hitches 
his  team  to  his  wagon,  stops  at  the  giate  of  his  first  neigh- 
bor, takes  his  savings,  gives  a  receipt,  and  jots  down  his 
order  for  what  farm  supplies  he  needs.  Thus  he  goes  down 
the  road,  stopping  at  every  gate.  When  he  gets  to  town  he 
deposits  the  money  collected  in  the  name  of  the  society  in  the 
best  bank.  Then  he  goes  to  some  wholesale  house,  loads 
his  wagon  or  wagons  with  enough  supplies  to  fill  the  orders 
given  to  him,  draws  a  bill  on  the  bank  in  payment,  drops 
the  supplies  ordered  at  each  gate  on  his  way  back,  and 
when  he  reaches  home,  credits  the  members  with  their  cash 
and  debits  them  with  the  wholesale  price  of  the  supplies 
received. 

At  the  end  of  the  month,  in  the  school  house  or  at  the 
church  an  hour  before  service,  the  managers  hold  an  open 
meeting  attended  by  all  members  who  desire  to  be  present. 
An  extra  man  perhaps  is  engaged  to  help  in  the  collecting 
and  hauling;  the  accounts  of  the  secretary-treasurer  are 
checked  up,  and  a  committee  is  appointed  to  recruit  new 
members  living  along  the  lanes  crossing  the  road  and  to 
induce  persons  not  qualified  for  membership  to  become  de- 
positors. Since  the  members  and  depositors  save  more 
than  they  spend,  the  society's  balance  at  the  bank  begins  to 
grow  and  it  is  soon  ready  to  grant  a  few  loans.  Some 
Saturday  evening  or  Sunday  morning  the  managers  consider 
applications  and  approve  that  which  appears  most  safe  and 
urgent.  If  this  is  done  at  a  called  meeting,  however,  the 
members  may  overrule  the  act  of  the  managers  and  take 
any  other  course  they  desire  because  the  supreme  power  of 
the  society  is  always  lodged  with  them. 

Now  the  applicant  is  not  granted  the  loan  at  any  lower 
interest  rate  than  prevails  in  the  locality,  because  the  society 


476  EURAL   CEEDITS 

is  not  a  benevolent  institution  in  any  respect.  It  is  paying 
interest  on  deposits  received,  out  of  which  the  loan  has 
been  made,  it  has  some  small  expenses  to  meet,  as  the  sal- 
aries of  the  secretary-treasurer  and  employees,  rent,  etc., 
and  above  all  it  is  trying  to  accumidate  a  reserve  so  as  to 
protect  members  against  losses.  All  this  must  come  from 
the  interest  charges  which,  with  the  small  profits  of  the 
trading  business,  are  the  chief  sources  of  its  income.  Event- 
ually, however,  borrowers  may  be  granted  loans  at  a  slightly 
reduced  rate,  when  the  increasing  reserve  strengthens  the 
standing  of  the  society  and  enables  it  to  attract  cheaper  de- 
posits and  rely  more  largely  on  its  own  unborrowed  funds 
for  making  loans.  But  a  borrower  is  never  charged  com- 
missions or  costs  for  examining  the  loan,  because  the  man- 
agers are  neighbors  and  are  supposed  to  have  knowledge 
of  his  solvency  and  the  value  of  the  security  offered,  while 
he  may  obtain  longer  periods  and  easier  terms  for  renewal, 
since  these  neighbors  understand  agricultural  conditionsi 
better  and  will  be  more  considerate  with  him  in  hard  times 
than  woxdd  the  ordinary  banker.  Moreover,  there  are  no 
heavy  legal  expenses  in  the  event  of  default  because  a  bor- 
rower would  not  dare  to  try  to  beat  his  neighbors  out  of 
their  Just  dues  if  he  expected  to  live  in  peace  in  the  neigh- 
borhood. 

These  benefits  alone  would  make  the  society  preferred  to 
the  ordinary  banks  or  private  individuals  as  a  lender,  and 
it  would  gradually  increase  its  membership  and  absorb  all 
the  business  along  that  five-mile  stretch  of  road.  Then  per- 
haps it  would  need  to  borrow  in  order  to  take  care  of  the 
business,  and  this  it  could  do  without  difficulty  because 
there  would  not  be  a  banker  in  the  town  who  would  not 
be  wiUiag  to  lend  on  the  collective  liability  of  the  mem- 
bers all  the  money  the  society  might  require.  Some  of  the 
members  might  die,  get  sick,  lose  their  farms,  or  move  away, 
but  according  to  the  law  of  averages  by  which  the  risks  in 
all  business  are  determined,  enough  would  remain  to  meet 
every  engagement  of  the  society.  Now  these  risks  would  be 
practically  non-existent  either  to  members  or  to  the  lender. 


PRINCIPLES  OP  COOPEEATIVE   CREDIT    477 

because,  assuming  that  proper  legislation  existed,  the  masi- 
mum  of  liabilities  which  the  society  might  incur,  either  for 
deposits,  borrowed  money  or  any  other  kind  of  obligation, 
would  be  fixed  by  the  articles  of  agreement  and  known  to  all. 
Long  before  that  maximum  was  reached  the  members  when 
they  saw  that  a  bad  loan  might  eat  up  the  reserve,  might 
settle  the  loss  by  a  small  pro  rata  contribution  and  change 
the  management  or  dissolve  the  society  at  once  and  begin 
all  over  again.    This  is  why  there  never  has  been  a  failure 
in  a  Eaiffeisen  credit  society  causing  loss  to  a  depositor  or 
a  creditor;  nor  has  there   ever  been   any  burdensome   or 
unequal  assessments  on  members,  because  constant  vigilance 
prevents  many  bad  loans,  and  the  little  losses  which  have 
occurred  have  been  met  by  raising  the  interest  rates  of  the 
borrowers  or  the  wholesale  prices  of  supplies  sold  to  members. 
Hence  the  EaifEeisen  form  seems  to  be  the  safest  for 
a  rural  credit  society.     There  need  be  no  shares,  for  why 
should  members  wish  to  make  dividends  out  of  themselves? 
The  shares  in  a  true  cooperative  society  have  no  voting 
power;  that  belongs  to  the  membership   certificate.     The 
share  capital  is  simply  time  deposits  serving  incidentally  and 
only  in  part  as  a  guaranty  fund.    In  a  Eaiffeisen  credit  so- 
ciety the  transactions  are  guaranteed  by  a  portion  of  the 
reserves,  while  the  deposits  are  savings  and  current  accounts 
as  in  an  ordinary  bank;  the  Eaiffeisen  society  therefore  has 
one  fund  less  to  handle  and  consequently  is  less  compli- 
cated than  an  association  with  shares.    Its  members,  if  they 
have  idle  cash,  place  it  on  deposit  and  draw  interest  at  as 
high  a  rate  as  that  of  any  possible  dividends  on  shares. 
Shares  and  dividends  create  a  distinction  between  invest- 
ing members  and  borrowing  members  which  interferes  with 
the  harmony  which  ought  to  reign  in  an  association  of  neigh- 
bors and  leads  to  corporation  practices  with  profit  as  the 
main  object.     Corporations  or  associations  with  shares  exist 
in  agricultural  cooperative  systems  and  are  practically  in- 
dispensable for  the  higher  institutions  which  center  around 
the  unions  and  federations,  but  there  is  not  a  system  which 
would  not  be  better  if  its  basic  units  were  all  little  neigh- 


478  EUKAL   CKEDITS 

borhood  clubs,  like  the  Eaiffeisen  credit  societies,  without 
shares  or  dividends.  A  Eaiffeisen  credit  society  does  not 
strive  to  make  profits  out  of  the  necessities  of  one  class  of 
members  to  be  distributed  among  another  class.  Its  objects 
are  to  reduce  interest  rates  to  fair  figures,  to  make  col- 
lective purchases  at  wholesale  prices,  sometimes  to  make 
collective  sales,  and  to  gather  up  the  money  made  by  the 
farmers  and  their  friends  within  a  small  defined  area  for 
re-use  within  that  area,  so  that  the  farmers  may  employ  the 
wealth  which  they  create  first  for  fijiancing  their  own  under- 
taldngs  and  then  for  helping  farmers  in  other  localities. 

Now  after  the  supposed  credit  society  on  that  five-mile 
stretch  of  road  has  been  operating  for  a  year,  the  farmers 
on  the  next  road,  seeing  how  successful,  safe  and  conven- 
ient it  is,  would  form  a  credit  society,  and  so  on  with  the 
farmers  on  other  roads.  When  credit  societies  had  been 
formed  on  all  roads  converging  in  the  town,  the  managers 
would  get  together  and  form  a  union  to  look  after  their 
general  interests.  The  first  thing  done  by  the  union  would 
be  to  form  a  regional  bank  on  the  share  plan,  selling  the 
shares  to  the  local  credit  societies  and,  if  they  are  Tinable 
to  supply  aU  the  needed  capital,  to  individual  farmers  and 
even  outsiders.  With  the  establishment  of  the  regional 
bank,  the  local  credit  societies  would  all  be  interlocked  and 
their  resources  would  fiow  from  one  to  the  other,  the  re- 
gional bank  serving  as  the  means  of  communication  among 
them  and  with  the  outside  world.  After  this  financial  net- 
work had  been  spread  the  union  would  organize  corpora- 
tions or  rather  associations  with  shares  for  cooperative  buy- 
ing, selling  and  manufacturing,  etc.,  and  thus  all  the  farm- 
ers in  that  region  would  become  organized  cooperatively, 
just  as  it  has  been  done  ia  Germany.  When  this  region  has 
been  organized,  other  regions  would  organize  in  the  same 
way.  The  unions,  with  oflBcers  consisting  of  experienced  and 
capable  farmers  and  other  persons  identified  with  agricul- 
ture, would  see  to  the  supervision,  inspection  and  auditing  of 
their  local  credit  societies  and  regional  banks  and  associa- 
tions, which  would  finally  be  linked  together  through  the 


PEINCIPLES  OF  COOPEEATIVB   CEEDIT    479 

tmions  by  state  and  national  federations  with  central  insti- 
tutions. There  is  every  prospect  for  enduring  success  for 
such  a  system  provided  the  component  parts  would  avoid 
real-estate  credit  and  land  transactions  and  keep  their  assets 
in  circulatory  form,  habitually  extending  only  short-term 
credit  on  easily  negotiable  securities. 

There  are  no  federal  or  state  laws  in  the  United  States 
■under  which  the  farmers  might  organize  themselves  iato 
systems  with  credit  societies  as  the  basic  units.  The  laws 
of  Massachusetts  on  credit  unions  of  1909,  of  Texas  on 
rural  credit  unions  of  1913,  of  Wisconsin  on  cooperative 
credit  associations  of  1913,  and  of  New  York  on  credit 
unions  as  finally  enacted  in  1914,  provide  for  the  organiza- 
tion of  associations  intended  for  thrift  and  small  credit  for 
feeble  folk.  Texas  limits  the  loans  to  $200  at  not  over  six 
per  cent  for  productive  purposes,  thus  absolutely  preventing 
large  undertakings,  while  the  restrictive  measures  of  aU  four 
laws  render  them  useless  for  rural  banking  and  credit  sys- 
tems. All  require  the  members  to  be  natural  persons;  none 
allows  assoeiational  members.  This  alone  would  prevent 
credit  societies  from  being  the  basic  units  of  a  system.  All 
forbid  tie  acceptance  of  deposits  from  outsiders,  thus  clos- 
ing the  greatest  source  of  funds  for  operations.  All  require 
share  capital  and  prohibit  the  societies  from  doing  any  other 
business  and  from  using  their  funds  for  any  other  purpose 
than  that  of  making  loans.  This  rejection  of  Eaiffeisen 
principles  is  the  most  serious  and  regrettable  defect  in  the 
laws.  The  farmers  of  the  United  States  are  capable  and 
independent  men  and  they  should  have  the  right  under  the 
laws  to  organize  themselves  as  best  suits  their  own  ideas  or 
circumstances,  whether  it  be  in  associations  with  shares  or 
without  shares  or  vnth  collective  liability  limited  or  imlim- 
ited.  Moreover,  they  should  be  able  to  decide  for  them- 
selves whether  they  wiU  have  syndicated  local  associations 
or  just  one  Eaiffeisen  credit  society  for  each  neighborhood. 
They  have  no  choice  under  any  of  these  laws,  and  thus  the 
play  of  private  initiative  and  freedom  of  action  is  blocked. 


480  EUEAL   CEEDITS 

The  use  of  the  word  "union"  is  wrong.  The  misuse  of  this 
word  evidently  is  due  to  an  erroneous  translation  of  the 
French  word  syndicat  in  the  Quebec  law  which  the  drafters 
of  the  Massachusetts  law  used  as  their  model.  Unless  this 
word  is  changed,  another  word  will  have  to  be  employed  to 
designate  the  second  degree  of  organization  in  an  agricul- 
tural cooperative  system.  If  this  were  done  it  would  pre- 
cipitate in  confusion  the.  statutes  and  literature  on  the  sub- 
ject in  European  minds.  It  is  safe  to  predict  that  except 
in  scattered  instances  there  will  be  no  rural  cooperative 
credit  societies  formed  under  the  Massachusetts,  Texas,  Wis- 
consin and  E"ew  York  laws  if  they  are  not  materially 
amended. 

The  first  step  to  be  taken  in  order  to  extend  cooperation 
and  to  introduce  cooperative  credit  among  farmers  is  of 
course  the  enactment  of  proper  legislation.  Already  there 
are  good  laws  on  cooperative  associations  in  many  states. 
These  ought  to  be  codified  in  every  state  and  the  bad  laws 
repealed.  Wherever  it  could  be  done  without  interfering 
with  present  development  and  existing  conditions,  the  laws 
on  cooperation  in  each  state  should  be  reduced  to  one  statu- 
tory act.  There  does  not  have  to  be  one  law  for  credit 
societies  and  separate  laws  for  associations  for  other  coop- 
erative purposes.  One  law  could  be  made  to  fit  them  all,  and 
this  would  be  the  best  plan  because  then  the  regulations 
would  become  standardized  as  regards  organization,  adminis- 
tration and  management.  The  farmers  of  the  United  States 
do  not  need  any  special  privileges  or  state  aid.  If  methods 
were  simplified  and  technicalities  eliminated,  cooperation,  or 
organized  individualism  based  on  private  initiative  and  mu- 
tual self-help,  would  eventually  be  applied  to  all  their  activ- 
ities. They  would  accomplish  this  most  quickly  and  suc- 
cessfully by  starting  with  the  credit  society  as  the  local  unit 
formed  and  operated  on  the  principles  of  Kaiffeisen. 


INDEX 


Acceptances,  279 

Administration  and  Sales  Co- 
operative Society,  Ger- 
many, 305 

Advance  to  Settlers'  Act  of,- 
New  South  "Wales,  194 

Advance  to  Settlers  Office, 
New  Zealand,  195 

Agrarian  Credit  Institute  of 
Latium,  359,  360 

Agrarian  Credit  Institute  of 
Liguria,  362 

Agricultural  Bank  Act  of 
Queensland,  194 

Agricultural  Bank  Act  of 
Western  Australia,  193, 
194 

Agricultural  Bank  of  Egypt, 
187,  189 

Agricultural  Bank  of  the 
Philippines,  192,  193 

Agricultural  Cooperative 
Press,  298 

Agricultural    credit,    difficul- 
ties of,  468,  469 
in  the  United  States,  5,  8 
See   also   Land   credit    and 
Cooperative  credit. 

Agricultural  Credit  Bank, 
Eoumania,   406 

Agricultural  Credit  Board, 
Portugal,  421,  425 


Agricultural     credit     institu- 
tions.     See   Eural    co- 
operative   credit    socie- 
ties. 
Agricultural    Land    Commis- 
sion,    St.     Petersburg, 
169 
Agricultural     mutual     credit 
banks,  Portugal,  feder- 
ations of,  425 
loans  of,  423,  424 
organization   and  operation 

of,  422,  425 
statistics  for,  426 
Agricultural     mutual     credit 
system,    Portugal,   421, 
422 
central  bank  of,  425 
district  banks  of,  422,  425 
established  by  law  of  1911, 

420,  421 
local  banks  of,  422,  425 
slow  growth  of,  425,  426 
syndical  character  of,  419 
Agricultural  Organization  So- 
ciety for  England  and 
Wales,  439,  443,  449 
Agriculture,  cooperative  credit 
for,  260,  261.    See  also 
Eaifieisen  Societies  and 
£ural  cooperative  credit 
societies. 


481 


482 


INDEX 


AgricTilture,  in  Austria,  364, 
365 
in   Europe  in   early   nine- 
teenth century,  20 
in  Hungary,  370 
in  Ireland  in  1889,  440 
in  Japan,  433 
in  Luxemburg,  389,  390 
in  the  United  States,  6,  9 

needs  of,  7 
land  credit  for,  in  France, 
128-135 
Albania,  no  cooperative  credit 

society  in,  413 
Algeria,    agricultural   mutual 

credit  system  in,  437 
Alkmaar  Central  Bank,  Hol- 
land,  388 
Alsace-Lorraine,  union  of,  300 
Amortization,    advantages   of, 
20 
debentures  necessary  for,  22 
effect  of  operation  of,  22,  23 
French  method  of,  18,  19, 

21,  22 
German  landschaft's  method 

of,  21,  85 
history  of,  19 

in  Italian  savings  banks,  143 
Italian    and    Japanese 

method    of,   219 
obligatory  in  Boden-Eiedit 

Institut,  165 
possible    only    for    certain 

lenders,  22 
under  Chilean  system,  205 
under  Credit  Agricole  mu- 
tual system,  134 
Amortization  fund  of  Silesian 

landschaft,  64,  70,  75 
Andorra,  Republic  of,  French 


cooperative  banks  avail- 
able for,  426 
Anhausen,  first  Eaiffeisen  so- 
ciety   formed    at,    259, 
285 
"Annual    societies"    in   Hun- 

gaiy,  371 
Annuities,  calculation  of,   19 
Credit   Foncier   loans   pay- 
able by,  118 
payable  on  long-term  loans 
in     foreign     countries, 
211,  212 
payable  to  land-credit  insti- 
tutions, 219 
under   Credit  Foncier   sys- 
tem, 122 
under  Italian  system  of  land 

credit,  142,  144 
under  Peasants'  State  Land 
Bank    system,    Bussia, 
171 
under    Silesian    landschaft 
system,  62-64,  66 
disposition  of,  68,  69 
use  of,  by  land-credit  insti- 
tutions, 221 
Argentine      National      Land 

Bank,  202 
Argentine    EepubUc,    Jewish 
agricultural  colony  in, 
455 
land-credit    institutions    of, 
202,  203 
Artel,  Eussian,  396 
Assignats,  27,  31 
Assington,  first  English  rural 
cooperative   association 
at,  254 
Aussig,   early  credit   associa- 
tion at,  365 


IOT)EX 


483 


Australia,  land  credit  in,  193- 
195 

long-term  loans  in,  211 
Austria,   agricultural  popula- 
tion of,  364,  365 

cooperative   federations    of, 
367,  368 

early      cooperative      move- 
ments in,  364 

legislation    on    cooperative 
credit  in,  370 

long-term  loans  in,  211 

project  for  Central  national 
bank  in,  370 

provincial   mortgage   insti- 
tutions of,  161,  162 

rural      cooperative      (Eaif- 
feisen)  societies  in,  366, 
367 
privileges  of,  369,  370 

Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  in, 
365,  366 

state  and  provincial  aid  to 
agricultural  cooperation 
in,  368-370 
Austria-Hungary,   cooperative 
credit  in,  364-379 

land-credit  in,  161-168,  219. 
See  also  Austria  and 
Himgary. 
Austrian  savings  banks, 
method  of,  of  extin- 
guishing loans,  18 
Avramovitch,  457 

first    cooperative    bank    in 
Servia  founded  by,  407 

Baden,  imion  of,  300 

banking  method  of,  306 
Balkan      States,      cooperative 
credit  ia,  405-414 


Baltic  provinces,  land  credit 
in,  218 
Territorial     Credit    Estab- 
lishment for,  174 

Banco  Hipotecario  del  Uru- 
guay, 205 

Banco  Hipotecario  Nacional, 
Argentine  Kepublic,  202 

Bank  for  Cooperative  Asso- 
ciations, 322 

Bank  for  Laborers'  Holdings 
and  Dwellings,  Nor- 
way, 184-186 

Bank  of  Algeria,  437 

Bank  of  England,  founding  of, 
24 

Bank  of  France,  agricultural 
credit  and,  333-335, 
342,  343 

Bank  of  Naples,  359 
management    of    provincial 
agricultural   banks   by, 
361 

Bank  of  Portugal,  relation  of, 
to  agricultural  mutual 
credit  system,  421,  424 

Bank  of  Kussia,  400 

services   of,  to   agriculture, 
400,  401 

Bank  of  Scotland,  270 

Bank  of  Sicily,  361 

Bank  of  Silesian  landschaft, 
56,  58,  67 

Bank  of  Spain,  418 

Bank  of  Western  Australia, 
193,  194 

Bank  fund  of  Silesian  land- 
schaft, 70 

Banks,  agricultural  mutual 
credit,  Portugal,  422- 
426 


484 


INDEX 


Banks,  in  Switzerland,  393 
land.  See  Land  banks, 
land-credit,     Germany,     94, 

95,  104-110 
land-improvement    annuity, 

Germany,  95-97 
rent-cliarge,     in    Germany, 

97-100 
rural,  Finland,  173 
savings.  See  Savings  banks. 
Sdhulze-Delitzsch    People's. 
See    Schulze  -  Delitzscb 
People's  Banks. 
Barbadoes,   credit  society   in, 

438 
Baroda,  Protectorate  of,  spe- 
cial law  for,  430 
Baron  de  Hirsch  fund,  451, 

452 
Bastiat,   Claude-Prederic,  life 

and  principles  of,  269 
Bavaria,  union  of,  300 
Bavarian    Hop   Growers'    So- 
ciety, failure  of,  304 
Bavarian   Mortgage  and  Ex- 
change   Bank    of    Mu- 
nich, 104,  105,  108 
Belgium,  Boerenbond  or  Peas- 
ants'   League    of,   383, 
385 
central  bank  of,  386 
comptoirs      agricoles      and 
General    Pensions    and 
Savings   Bank  of,  383, 
384 
cooperative  credit  early  de- 
vised in,  380 
cooperative   credit  societies 

in,  382,  383 
Credit   Union    of   Brussels 
in,  380-382 


Belgium,  credit  unions  in,  382 
first  cooperation  law  in,  382 
legislation    on     cooperative 

credit  in,  383 
life  insurance  as  security  in, 

384 
rural  cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties in,  385,  386 
syndicats  in,  385 
Beluze,  322 
Bemat,  Stephen,  372 
Bemhardi,  Dr.,  257,  265 
Bevan,  William,  414 
Bey,  Omar  Lufly,  the  father 
of  cooperation  in  Egypt, 
436,  457 
Bichelsee,    Switzerland,   rural 
cooperative    credit    so- 
ciety in,  392 
Bismarck,  108,  257,  267 
Blanc,  Louis,  321 
Board    of   Agriculture,    Scot- 
land, 151-153 
Board     of     Agriculture     Eind 
Pisheries,    Great    Brit- 
ain, 158-160 
Board  of  Public  Works,  Ire- 
land, 153,  154 
Board  of  supervision  of  Caisse 
Populaire,  448 
of  people's  banks,  277,  278 
of       Eaiffeisen       societies, 
289 
Boden-Kxedit  Institut,   Him- 
gary,  founding  of,  164 
loans  of,  165,  166 
organization    and   adminis- 
tration of,  164,  165 
statistics  of,  166 
Boerenbond  of  Belgium,  384, 
386 


INDEX 


485 


Bonnard      Excliange     Bank, 

Marseilles,   322 
Bouvet,  Paul,  322 
Brandenburg,   landechaft    in, 

85 
Brazil,  Jewish  farmers  in,  455 
British   India,   central  banks 
in,  431,  432 
cooperative   credit   laws    of 

1904  and  1912  in,  430 
cooperative   credit  societies 

of,  430-432 
early  forms  of  cooperation 

in,  428 
economic  conditions  in,  42Y, 

428 
history  of  cooperative  credit 

in,  429 
statistics      on      cooperative 

credit  in,  432 
work     of     Nicholson     and 
Wolff    for    cooperative 
credit  in,  429,  430 
Buerman,       organizer      with 
Bemhardi    of   first   co- 
operative bank,  25Y 
Building  and  loan  associations 
in   the   United    States, 
statistics  for,  457 
See  also   Savings  and  loan 
associations. 
Building     loans     of     Banco 
Eipotecario     Nacional, 
Argentine  Republic,  202 
of    Norwegian     Bank    for 
Laborers'  Holdings  and 
Dwellings,  185 
Building     operations,     super- 
vision    of,     by     Sous- 
Comptoirs    des    Entre- 
preneurs, 129,  130 


Bulgaria,     Central     Agricul- 
tural Bank  of,  410,  411 
Central    Cooperative    Bank 

of,  412,  413 
farmers'  banks  of,  409,  410 
rural  credit  societies  of,  411, 
4l2 

Bureau  for  non-members  of 
the  Silesian  landsehaft, 
56,  57,  58 

Bureau  of  Supervision  and 
Control  of  the  Ministry 
of  Agriculture,  France, 
324,  337 

Biiring,  plan  of,  for  land 
credit,  38-42 

Cairo,  first  cooperative  society 

in  Egypt  at,  436 
Caisse     Populaire,     establish- 
ment of,  445 
influence    of,     in    forming 

other  banks,  446 
organization  and  operations 

of,  447-449 
similarity  of,  to  American 
mutual   savings   banks, 
446 
statistics  of,  445,  446 
Caja  de  Credito  Hipotecario, 

Chile,  203-205 
Caja    Prestamos    para    Obras 
de  Irrigacion  y  Fomen- 
to    de    la    Agricultura, 
Mexico,  201,  202 
Canada,  Caisse  Populaire,  445- 
449 
cooperative  banks  in,  450 
Jewish  farmers  in,  455 
legislation    on    cooperative 
credit  in,  449,  450 


4:86 


INDEX 


Canada,  movement  for  cooper- 
ative credit  in,  450,  451 
people's  banks  in,  446.    See 

also  Caisse  Populaire. 
trading  monopoly  in,  251 

Carey,  Henry  Charles,  269 
Schulze-Delitzsch's     knowl- 
edge of,  256 

CasasTis,  Joaquin  D.,  196 

Cash  credit,  279 

in  Italian  people's  banks,  352 
origin  of,  271 

Casimir-Perier,  324 

Casse  Ademprivili  of  Sar- 
dinia, 361,  362 

Catholic  banks  in  Italy,  353, 
354 

Catholic  rural  credit  societies 
in  Italy,  357,  358 

Cattle-purchasing  commis- 
sions  in  Switzerland, 
394 

Cattle  Selling  Society,  Ger- 
many, 303 

Celleiros  communs,  Portu- 
guese, 420,  421 

Central  Agricultural  Bank  of 
Bulgaria,  410,  411 

Central  Agricultural  Cooper- 
ative Bank  at  Darm- 
stadt, failure  of,  305, 
306 

Central     Agricultural     Loan 
Bank,     Germany,    290, 
304,  306,  308 
branches  of,  306,  308 
method    of,    of    extending 

credit,  308 
relations  of,  with  Prussian 
Central        Cooperative 
Bank,  311 


Central  Agricultural  Loan 
Bank,  statistics  of, 
309 
withdrawal  of,  from  Im- 
perial Federation  of 
Germany,  303 

Central  Association  of  Co- 
operative Societies  of 
Japan,  434,  435 

Central  Bank  for  Agricultural 
Loans,  France,  132 

Central  Bank  for  People's 
Banks  and  Cooperative 
Societies,  Eoumania, 
405,  406 

Central  Bank  of  Agricultural 
Credit,  Lisbon,  425 

Central  banks:  British  India, 
431,  432 
Germany,  306-309 
Holland,  387,  388 
Eussia,  402 
Servia,  408 

Central  Cooperative  Bank  for 
England  and  Wales, 
444,  445 

Central  Cooperative  Bank  of 
Bulgaria,  412,  413 

Central  Cooperative  Credit 
Establishment  of  Fin- 
land,  404 

Central  Federation  of  Agri- 
cultural Syndicates  of 
France,  324,  337 

Central  Federation  of  People's 
Credit,  France,  323 

Central  Landschaft  of  Prus- 
sia, 89-91 

Central  Society  of  German 
Wine  Growers,  failure 
of,  304 


INDEX 


487 


Centre.  See  Hungarian  Cen- 
tral Society  for  Co- 
operative Credit. 

Chambers  of  agriculture,  Ger- 
many, 301 

Character  Credit,  271,  467, 
468 

Charity,  attitude  of  Schulze- 
Delitzsch  banks  toward, 
274 
effect  of,  on  cooperation,  261 

Chegaray  report  on  land  credit 
in  France,  112 

Chile,  land  credit  in,  203-205 
long-term  loans  in,  211 

Chilean  State  Land  Mortgage 
Bank,  203-205 

Chosen  Bank,  Japan,  189 

Circles  of  the  Silesian  land- 
schaft,  54-56 

Collective  purchasing  by  rural 
cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties, 472,  473 

Collective  saving,  distin- 
guished from  coopera- 
tive credit,  241 

Colonial  Bank  for  Hokkaido, 
Japan,  189 

Cornices,  330 

Committee   of    arbitrators    of 
Italian  people's  banks, 
352 
of  control,  of  Italian  peo- 
ple's banks,  351 
of  Italian  rural  credit  so- 
cieties, 355 
of  management  of  Baiffeisen 

societies,  289 
of  supervision,  of  Hungar- 
ian Boden-Kredit  Insti- 
tut,  164 


Committee  of  supervision,  of 

Hungarian  Centre,  374 

of  Italian  savings  banks, 

141,  142 

on    credit    of    the    Caisse 

Populaire,  448 
on  "honor,"  of  Italian  peo- 
ple's banks,   352 
on  risks,  of  Italian  people's 
banks,  352 
Commutation  and  redemption 
of  lands   in   Germany, 
98 
Company  of  the  West,  John 

LaVs,  26,  250 
Comptoir       National       d'Es- 

compte,  128 
Comptoirs  agricoles,  Belgium, 

383,  384 
Compulsory  audit,  feature  of 
German  cooperative  so- 
cieties, 302,  303 
Congested  Districts  Board  of 
Ireland,  154 
assistance  to,  from  Estates 
Commissioners,  157 
Connecticut,  early  land  credit 

in,  29 
Consumptive  credit,  3 
"Contractualists,"  163 
"Conversion,"     epoch    of,    in 
history      of      German 
landschafts,  82,  83 
Cooperation,  advent  of  mod- 
em type  of,  254,  255 
definition  of,  247 
effect  of  state  aid  or  charity 

on,  261 
in  the  United  States,  457- 

460 
origin  of,  253 


488 


INDEX 


Cooperation,  Schulze-Delitzsch 
theory  of,  256-258 
Socialism  and,  253,  254 
work  of  Eaiffeisen  on,  258- 
260 
Cooperation    in    Agriculture, 

4M 
Cooperative   associations,    ad- 
ministration    of,     247, 
248 
advantages  of,  250 
agricultural,  advantages  of, 

261,  262 
best  type  of,  262 
systems  of,  260,  261 
See    also   Rural   coopera- 
tive credit  associations, 
classes  adapted  to,  249,  250 
distinguished  from  partner- 
ships and  corporations, 
248,  249 
early  English,  254,  255 
early  European,  255 
early  type  of,  250,  251 
essential  feature  of,  249,  349 
members'  liability  in,  248 
members'    subscriptions   in, 

248 
object  of,  249 
origin  of  modem  movement 

for,  255,  256 
three  types  of,  260 
See  also  Cooperative  credit 
societies ;    for    coopera- 
tive associations  in  any 
of  the  various  countries 
see  name  of  country. 
Cooperative    banking    system 
for  farmers,  9.  See  also 
Cooperative  Credit. 
Cooperative  banks  in  France,  1 


advances  to,  by  Bank  of 
France,  335 
Cooperative  banks  in  France, 
early,  322 

in  Germany,  306-312 

in  Italy,  347,  348 

in  Boumania,  405,  406 

in  Servia,  407,  408 

See  also  Cooperative  credit 
societies. 
Cooperative  cattle  buying  in 

Switzerland,  393,  394 
Cooperative  cheese  factories  in 
the  United  States,  460 
Cooperative  creameries  in  the 

United  States,  460 
Cooperative  credit,  4 

first  appearance  of,  254 

in  Algeria,  437 

in    Austria-Himgary,    364- 
379 

in  Balkan  States,  405-414 

in  Barbadoes,  438 

in  Belgium,    380-386 

ia  British  India,  427-432 

in  Bulgaria,  409-413 

in  Canada,  445-451 

in  Cyprus,  413,  414 

in  Denmark,  389,  390 

in  Egypt,  435-437 

in  England  and  Wales,  439, 
443-445 

in  European  Turkey,  413 

in  Finland,  403,  404 

in  France,  321-345 

in     French    West     Africa, 
438 

in  German  Southwest  Afri- 
ca, 438 

in  Germany,    present     sys- 
tems of,  296-320 


INDEX 


489 


Cooperative    credit    in    Ger- 
many, EaifEeisen  system 
of,  281-295 
Sclmlze-Delitzscli  People's 

Banks,  263-280 
system    of,     smmnarized, 
312,  313 
in  Guinea,  438 
in  Holland,   386-389 
in  Ireland,  439-443 
in  Italy,  346-363 
in  Jamaica,  438 
in  Japan,  432-435 
in  Java,  438 
in  Luxemburg,  388,  389 
in  New  England,  27 
in  Norway,  391 
in  Palestine,  414 
in  Portugal,  419-426 
in  Eepublic  of  Andorra,  426 
in  Eoumania,  405,  406 
in  Eussia,  395-404 
in  Scotland,  445 
in  Servia,  407-409 
in  Spain,  415-419 
in  Sweden,    391 
in  Switzerland,   392-394 
in  Tunis,  437,  438 
in  United  States,  451-455 
origin  of,  257-260,  285 
principles  of,  and  their  ap- 
plication, 456-480 
spread   of,   in  Europe   and 
Asia,  456,  457 
Cooperative    credit    societies, 
administration  of,  464, 
465 
advantages  of,  469,  470 
associations  of  persons,  not 
aggregations  of  capital, 
462 


Cooperative    credit    societies, 
cheap  credit  not  grant- 
ed by,  466,  468 
compulsory  audit  of,  465 
countries  where  most  highly 

developed,  457 
functions  of,  466 
in  Algeria,  437 
in  Belgium,  382,  383 
in  British  India,  organiza- 
tion and  operation  of, 
430,  431 
privileges  of,  431 
statistics  for,  432 
supervision  and  inspection 
of,  431 
in  Egypt,  436,  437 
in  England  and  Wales,  444 
in  Einland,  404 
in  France,   distinguished 
from   syndicats,   330 
local.     See  Eural  cooper- 
ative banks, 
relation     of,    to    Ereneh 
syndicats,  322,  333 
in    Germany,    land  -  credit 
business  of,  104 
local,  313 

organization    and    opera- 
tion of,  313-318 
source  of  funds  of,  318 
statistics  of,  316,  319 
in  Hungary,  372,  373 
affiliated  with  the  Centre, 

375-378 
defects  of,  378,  379 
not    affiliated    with    the 
Centre,  379 
in  Italy,  legislation  on,  349, 

350 
in  Japan,  434,  435 


490 


INDEX 


Cooperative    credit    societies, 
in  Quebec,  450 
provisions  for,  449,  450 
in  Eoumania,  405,  406 
federations  of,  406 
state  aid  to,  406 
in  Eussia,  398,  399 
federations  of,  399,  400 
history  of,  396,  397 
statistics  of,  399 
types  of,  398,  399 
in  Tunis,  437 
interest    rates    of,    normal, 

467,  468 
limitation  of  dividends  in, 

467 
multiple  voting  in,  462 
need  of  deposits  in,  466 
organizers  of,  456,  457 
real-estate  mortgages  taken 

by,  467,  468 
security  always  required  by, 

467,  468 
type  of  legislation  required 
for,  465,  466 
Cooperative      elevators      and 
granaries  in  tbe  United 
States,  460 
Cooperative     land-purchasing 

societies,  Pinland,  173 
Cooperative  savings  and  loan 
societies,  Russian,  398, 
399 
statistics  of,  399 
Cooperative     Tobacco     Sales 

Society,  304 
Corporations,      disadvantages 
of,  250 
distinguished    for    coopera- 
tive   associations,    248, 
249 


Corporations,  effect  of  rise  of, 
252,  253 
French  law  of  1867  on,  328 
history  of,  251-253 
Costa  Eica,  state  land-mort- 
gage bank  of,  205 
Coimselors    of    the     Silesian 

landschaft,  47,  48 
County    credit    and    savings 

banks,  Eussia,  401 
County  Credit  Association  of 
Pesth     Philis-Solt-Kis- 
kun,  372 
Courland,    Eussia,    territorial 
credit  establishment  for, 
174 
Creamery  associations  in  Ire- 
land, 441 
Credit,    agricultural,    in    the 
United  States,  5-8 
See  also  Land  credit, 
consumptive,  3 
cooperative,    4.      See    also 

Cooperative  credit, 
definition  of,  3 
forms  of,  3 
inadequacy    of,    in    United 

States,  5 
individual,  4 

kinds  of,  needed  by  agricul- 
ture, 7 
land,  3.  See  also  Land  credit, 
long-term,  3,  4,  7,  8 
productive,  3 
real-estate,  use  of,  7 
security  for,  3 
short-term,  8 

securities  for,  3,  4 
sources  of,  in  United  States, 

7 
wide  extent  of,  4 


INDEX 


491 


Credit  agricole  en  France  et 

a  I'Etranger,  322 
Credit  Agricole  Mutuel,  132- 
134,  324 

Bank  of  France  and,  343 

connection  of,  with  the  Cen- 
tral Federation  of  Agri- 
cultural Syndicats,  324 

debt  of,  to  the  state,  343 

life  insurance  accepted  as 
security  by,  207 

local  banks  of,  324,  338-341 

organization  of,  337 

possible  future  sources  of 
funds  of,  343 

provisions  of  law,  creating, 
335,  336 

regional  banks  of.  See 
Eural  regional  banks. 

statistics  for,  1912,  323,  324, 
340 

subject  to  Bureau  of  Super- 
vision and  Control  of 
Ministry  of  Agricul- 
ture, 324 

system  of,  outlined,  337 
Credit     Foncier,     agriculture 
and,  131,  132 

area  of  operations  of,  117 

capital  stock  of,  116,  117 

debentures  of,  124-127 
lawful     investments     for 
rural  banks,  339 

disposal  of  earnings  of,  117 

establishment  of,  114,  324 

financially  embarrassed  by 
Societe  du  Credit  Agri- 
cole, 325 

limit  of  debenture  issue  of, 
221 

loans  of,  118-124 


Credit    Foncier,    objects    of, 
117,  131 
obligatory  reserve  of,  117 
organization  of,  115,  116 
privileges  of,  114,  127,  224 
prizes  given  by,  218,  222 
procedure  of,  in  cases  of  de- 
fault, 123 
relations    of,    with    Societe 
du  Credit  Agricole,  325, 
326 
reports  of,  127 
sources  of  funds  of,  118 
Sous-Comptoir    des    Entre- 
preneurs   de    Batiment 
controlled  by,  128 
special  reserves  of,  117 
statistics  of,  130,  131 
Credit  Foncier  Egyptien,  187, 

188 
Credit    Institution    for     All 

'Germany,  105 
Credit  Union  of  Brussels,  380- 

382 
Credit   Unions,   distinguished 
from     comptoirs     agri- 
coles,  383 
in  Belgium,  382 
in  Massachusetts,  479 
in  New  York,  479 
in  Texas,  479 
See  also  Cooperative  credit 
societies. 
Croatia-Slavonia,    family    co- 
operiative    societies    in, 
371 
Croatian  Agrarian  Bank,  379 
Cuba,  Territorial  Bank  of,  206 
"Curialists,"  163 
Cyprus,  cooperative  credit  in, 
413,  414 


493 


INDEX 


d'Andrimont,  Leon,  382,  383, 

456 
Daranyi,  Ignatius,  372 
Dartmouth  College  case,  252 
Debenture  bond,  litera  A,  60 

litera  B,  66 

litera  C,  61 

litera  D,  70 
Debentures,  24-33 

as  securities,  223 

Biiring's  plan  for  issuing, 
38-41 

characteristics  of,  32,  33 

definition  of,  17 

forms  of,  222 

long-term  loans  and,  222, 
223 

necessary  for  amortization, 
22 

new  series  of,  issued  by  old 
German  landschafts,  84 

of  agricultural  credit  asso- 
ciations, Italy,  147 

of  central  landschaft  of 
Prussia,  90 

of  Credit  Foncier,  124-127, 
131 

of  Credit  Eoneier  Egyptien, 
188 

of  Danish  land-credit  asso- 
ciations, 179 

of  German  public  land- 
credit  institutions,  93 

of  Hungarian  Boden-Kredit 
Institut,  166 

of  Hungarian  Central  So- 
ciety for  Cooperative 
Credit,  375 

of  Italian  savings  banks, 
143,  144 

of  kwango  ginko,  190,  191 


Debentures  of  land-credit  in- 
stitutions, 219-224 

of  Mexican  mortgage  banks, 
198,  199 

of  new  type  of  German  land- 
schafts, 88 

of  Norwegian  Bank  for 
Laborers'  Holdings  and 
Dwellings,  185 

of  old  type  of  landschafts 
other  than  Silesian,  80 

of  Peasants'  State  Land 
Bank,  Eussia,  171 

of  Provincial  Credit  Asso- 
ciation of  Posen,  83, 
84 

of  provincial  mortgage  asso- 
ciations, Austria,  161, 
162 

of  Prussian  Central  Land 
Credit  Company,  109, 
110 

of  rent-charge  banks,  99 

of  Silesian  landschaft,  60- 
66,  71-76 

of  special  cooperative  bank 
of  Bulgaria,  413 

of  Swiss  mortgage  banks, 
177 

origin  of,  26 

paper  money,  first  form  of, 
24 

privileges  attached  to,  223 

redemption  of,  by  land- 
credit  institutions,  221 

retirement  of,  by  land-credit 
companies,  221,  222 

security  of,  222 

use  of,  in  United  States,  8 
de  Besse,  Ludovic,  cooperative 
banks  of,  322 


INDEX 


493 


Decentralization,     as    distin- 
guished from  syndical- 
ism, 461 
de  Lavergne,  Leonce,  324 
del   Credere  Commissions,  in 
Belgic  Comptoirs  Agri- 
coles,  384 
Delitzsch   association  for   co- 
operative credit,  266 
Denmark,     collective    buying 
and  selling  in,  389 
home  colonization  policy  of, 

180 
land-credit   associations   of, 

1Y9 
land-credit  system  of,  218 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
mortgage     associations     of, 

1Y9,  180 
Mortgage  Bank  of,  180 
rural  cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties in,  389,  390,  461 
serial  issue  of  debentures  in, 
220,  221 
Department     of     Agriculture 
and  Technical  Instruc- 
tion, Ireland,  155 
Desjardins,   Alphonse,   activi- 
ties of,  for  cooperative 
credit  in  Canada,  446, 
450,  451,  457.    See  also 
Caisse  Populaire. 
promoter      of      cooperative 
credit  in  United  States, 
457 
Dieterici,  on  results  of  Seven 

Tears'  War,  36,  37 
Discount  and  Mortgage  Bank 

of  Bavaria,  206 
Discount  committee  of  Italian 
people's  banks,  351,  352 


Distributive  societies  of  Wil- 
liam Haas,  296 

District  boards  of  the  SOesian 
landschaft,  49-51 

District  managers  of  the  SUe- 
sian  landschaft,  49 

Dividends,  in  BaifFeisen  socie- 
ties, 287 
people's  banks  and,  276,  277 

Doneraile  credit  society,  441, 
442 

Donna  Eleonora,  Queen,  420 

Dorovatovo,  cooperative  loan 
and  savings  society  at, 
396 

Dresdener  Bank,  Germany, 
280 

Dual  monarchy.  Bee  Austria- 
Hungary. 

Duport,  syndical  banks 
founded    by,   333 

Durand,  Louis,  345,  366,  457 
first    BaifFeisen    society    in 
France  formed  by,  322, 
323 

Dussert,  323 

East    Indies,    monopolies    of 

companies  over,  250 
East   Prussia,   landschaft   of, 

77,  78,  81,  85,  86 
public  insurance  company 

founded  by,  207 
Economides,       organizer      of 

BaifEeisen     society     ia 

Cyprus,  414 
Egypt,  cooperative  credit  in, 

435-437 
land-credit   institutions   of^ 

187-189 
EUenbuxg  association  for  ea~ 


494 


INDEX 


operative  credit,  255, 
265 

Eindhoven  Central  Bank, 
HoUand,  387 

Emphyteusis,  146 

Endre,  371 

England.     See  Great  Britain. 

English  trade  unions,  254 

Equitable  Pioneers  of  Eoche- 
dale,  254,  255 

Ertl,  Dr.,  368 

Estates  Commissioners  of  Ire- 
land, 155,  157 

Esthonia,  territorial  credit 
establishment  for,  174, 
218 

Executive  committee  of  peo- 
ple's banks,  277 

Executive  council  of  the  Sile- 
sian  landschaft,  47,  48 
of  the  Swedish  General 
Mortgage  Bank,  182 

Expropriation,  217 

Earm-mortgage    bureaus    for 

non-members    of    Sile- 

sian      landschaft,      56, 

57 
Farmers'      Central      Trading 

Board,  439 
Earmers'     mutual     insurance 

companies.      United 

States,  459 
Earmers,      cooperation      best 

adapted  for,  249 
debt  of,  in  United  States, 

5-8 
long-term    loans    necessary 

for,  211 
Eederal  Eeserve  Act  of  1913, 

8,  9 


Federation  of  Dutch  Peasants, 
387 

Federation  of  Farmers'  and 
Workmen's  Banks  with 
Unlimited  Liability, 
France,  323,  345 

Federation  of  Industrial  and 
Economical  Coopera- 
tive Societies,  Germany, 
See  General  Federa- 
tion. 

Federation  of  Jewish  Farm- 
ers of  America,  453 

Federation  of  Sehulze  -  De- 
litzsch  Societies  of 
Austria,   366 

Feudalism,      distribution      of 
land  under,  12 
end  of,  11,  12,  14 

Finland,  cooperative  credit  in, 
403,  404 
land  credit  in,  173,  174,  218 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
Mortgage  Society  of,  174 

First  General  Hungarian 
Life  Insurance  Society, 
207 

Flammersfeld,  Germany,  Raif- 
feisen  credit  society  at, 
259,  285 

Formosa,  189 

Founders,  assembly  of  Hun- 
garian Boden  -  Eredit 
Institut,  164 

Fourier,  321 

France,     agricultural     condi- 
tions in  1852. 
cooperative  credit  system  in, 

outline  of,  237 
Credit  Agricole  Mutuel  of, 
323,  324,  337-344 


INDEX 


495 


France,    Credit    Foncier    of, 

114-127 

See  also  Credit  Foncier. 
credit  unions  in,  382 
early  efEorts  at  cooperation 

in,  255 
experiments  in  land  credit 

in,  27 
first  rural  cooperative  bank 

in,  332 
history  of  cooperative  credit 

in,  321-336 
history  of  land-credit  move- 
ment in,  111-114 
land  credit  in,  111-135.    See 

also  Credit  Foncier  and 

Sous-Comptoir  des  En- 
trepreneurs    de     Bati- 

ment. 
land  credit  for  agriculture 

in,  128-135,  218 
Credit   Agricole    Mutuel, 

132-134 
legislation    on    agricultural 

credit  in,  325-332,  335, 

336 
legislation   on    corporations 

in,  328 
l^islation  on  land  credit  in, 

111,  113,  114,  118,  132, 

133 
life  insurance  as  security  for 

loans  in,  207,  208 
limit  of  debenture  issues  in, 

221 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
mortgage  debt  in,  4 
precursors     of     cooperative 

credit  in,  321 
savings  banks  in,  and  their 

help  to  cooperation,  333 


France,   special  privileges  to 

land-credit    institutions 

in.  111,  224 

state     aid     to     cooperative 

credit  in,  343,  344,  469 

failure  of,  344,  345 

Frankfort-on-the-Main,  Bank 
of,  305 

Fraternal  Bank  for  Small 
Commerce,  Cognac,  322 

Frederick  the  Great,  36,  37,  38 
adoption   of   Biiring's    idea 

by,  42,  43 
amortization  under,  19 

French  Canada,  movement  for 
cooperative  credit  in, 
451 

French  West  Africa,  mutual 
aid  societies  in,  438 

French  Eevolution,   abolition 
of  corporations  and  as- 
sociations during,  328 
land  credit  during,  26 

Funds,  two  kinds  of,  needed 
by  agriculture,  7 

Galician  Boden-Kredit  Insti- 

tut,  162 
General  assembly,  of  Central 
Cooperative     Bank     of 
Bulgaria,  412,  413 
of  Credit  Foncier,  115,  116 
of  National     Land     Credit 
Institute      for      Small 
Landowners    of    Hun- 
gary, 166,  167 
of  people's  banks,  277 
of  Eaiffeisen  societies,  289 
of  Silesian  landschaft,  51-53 
General    Bank    of    Law    and 
Company,  25 


496 


INDEX 


General  Board  for  Small 
Credit,  Bank  of  Eussia, 
400 

General  commissions,  Ger- 
many, 97 

General    (Eaiffeisen)   Federa- 
tion, 290,  291,  299 
cooperative  banks  of,  306 
principle  of  self-Help  in,  279 
secession  of,  from  Imperial 
Federation,  297,  303 

General  Federation  of  People's 
Banks,  Germany,  279 

General  funds  of  the  Silesian 
landschaft,  69,  75 

General  Land  Drainage  and 
Improvement  Company 
for  England  and  Wales, 
159 

General  Pension  and  Savings 
Bank,  Belgium,  383,  384 

General  Union,  Servia,  408 

German  Federation  of  Aus- 
trian Agricultural  Co- 
operative Societies,  367, 
368 

German  landsehafts.  See 
Landschafts. 

German  savings  banks,  method 
of,  of  extruguishing 
loans,  18 

German  Southwest  Africa, 
credit  society  in,  438 

German  Wine  Grower's  So- 
ciety of  Palestine,  303 

Germany,  amortization  in,  19, 
20 
cooperative  banks   of,   306- 

312 
Council  of  Agriculture  of, 
301 


Germany,  fiduciary  agent  for 
land    mortgage    banks 
in,  213 
first  cooperative  associations 

in,  255 
General  Federation  of  Rural 
Cooperative       Societies 
of,  299.    See  also  Gen- 
eral   (Eaifieisen)    Fed- 
eration, 
land-credit    institutions    in, 
34,  217 
private,  102-110 

insurance    institutions, 

103,  104 
land-credit  banks,   104- 

110 
savings  banks,  102,  103 
public,   92-100 
general  commissions,  97 
land-credit  banks,  94,  95 
land-improvement      an- 
nuity banks,  95-97 
rent-charge     banks,      97- 
100 
settlement    commission, 
97 
See  also  Landschafts. 
land-credit  law  of  1899  in, 

105,   106 
life    insurance    as    security 

for  loans  in,  207 
limit  of  debenture  issues  in, 

221 
local  cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties in,  313-320 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
modem    cooperative    move- 
ment in,  255-260 
present  systems  of  coopera- 
tive credit  in,  296-320 


INDEX 


497 


Germany,  EaifFeisen  system 
in,  281-295.  See  also 
EaifFeisen  system. 

rural  cooperative  system  of, 
281-295,  469-472 
compulsory  audit  in,  302 
failures  in,  304,  305 
financing  of,  302 
summarized,  312,  313 

Schulze-Delitzscli  People's 
Banks  in,  263-280.  See 
also  Schulze  -  Delitzsch 
People's  Banks. 

second  mortgages  in,  209 

state  invalidity  and  old-age 
insurance     institutions 
in,  99,  100 
Gladstone,  156 

Gomez,  Valentin,  organizer  of 
first  cooperative  credit 
society,  417 
Great  Britain,  agricultural 
cooperative  movement 
in,  439 

Agricultural  Organization 
Society  of  England  and 
Wales  in,  439,  443,  444 

cooperative  credit  in,  444, 
445 

Farmers'  Central  Trading 
Board  of  England  in, 
439 

first  cooperative  associa- 
tions in,  254 

land-credit  experiments  in, 
24-26 

land  legislation  in,  156- 
160 

loans  granted  by  Develop- 
ment Commission  in, 
444 


Great  Britain,  nationalization 
of  land  in,  215 
Small  Holdings  and  Allot- 
ments Act  of  1908  in, 
148-151 
trade  unions  of,  254 
why  no  private  land-credit 

companies  in,  210 
See  also  Ireland  and  Scot- 
land. 
Greece,  no  cooperative  credit 

society  in,  413 
Guaranty    fund,    of    Schulze- 
Delitzsch    People's 
Banks,  276 
of  Silesian  landschaft,  70 
Guinea,  credit  society  in,  438 

Haas,     WiUiam,     compulsory 
audit  favored  by,  303 
distributive  societies  of,  296 
Imperial  Federation  of  Ag- 
ricultural    Cooperative 
Societies    foimded    by, 
297,  298 
Haeck,  Frangois,  380,  382,  383 
Heddesdorf,  259,  282,  283,  285 
Hesse,    activities   of  WiUiam 
Haas  in,  296,  297 
crisis  in  cooperative  move- 
ment in,  306 
Holland,  central  banks  of,  387, 
388 
early  efforts  at  cooperation 

in,  255 
Peasants'  Cooperative  Mort- 
gage Bank  of,  387 
rural  credit  societies  in,  387 
village  associations  in,  386 
Home    colonization    in    Den- 
mark, 180 


498 


INDEX 


Home    colonization,    in    Fin- 
land, 173 
in  New  Zealand,  195 
in  Sweden,  183 
Hotoku-sha,   original  ts^pe  of 
cooperative    credit    so- 
ciety in  Japan,  433 
Huber,  Victor  A.,  activities  of, 
for  cooperation,  255 
influence  of,  on  Sclmlze- 
Delitzsch,  256 
Hudson's  Bay  Company,  251 
Hungarian     Central     Society 
for  Cooperative  Credit, 
167,  207 
estabKshment  of,  373,  374 
organization   and  operation 

of,  374,  375 
powers  and  duties  of,  375 
privileges  of,  375 
shortcomings  of,  378,  379 
societies  affiliated  with,  375- 

377 
statistics   of,   378 
Hungarian     Land     Mortgage 

Institute,  374 
Hungarian     National     Land 
Credit      Institute      for 
Small  Landowners,  166 
Hungary,  agriculture  in,  370 
"annual  societies"  in,  371 
Boden-Kredit    Institut    of, 

164-166 
Central  Society  for  Cooper- 
ative Credit  in,  373-375, 
377,  378 
cooperative    credit   societies 

in,  375 
cooperative  organizations  in, 
independent    of    "Cen- 
tre," 379 


Hungary,  Count  Karolyi's  co- 
operative movement  in, 
372,  373 

early  attempts  at  coopera- 
tion in,  371 

early  history  of  land  credit 
in,  163 

Land  Credit  Institute  of, 
168 

legislation  on  cooperative 
credit  in,  373,  374,  379 

life  insurance  as  security  for 
loans  in,  207,  208 

long-term  loans  in,  211 

National  Federation  of 
Hungarian  Land  Credit 
Institutions  of,  167, 168, 
377 

National  Land  Credit  Insti- 
tute for  Small  Land- 
owners of,  166,  167,  377 

state  aid  to  cooperative 
credit  in,  373-375,  469 

successes  and  failures  of  co- 
operative system  in, 
378,  379 
Hussein,  Prince,  activities  of, 
for  cooperation  i  n 
Egypt,  436 

Imperial  Cooperative  Bank, 
Germany,  303,  306 

branches  of,  306,  307 

founding  of,  311 

statistics  of,  309 
Imperial  Federation  of  Agri- 
cultural       Cooperative 
Societies,  Germany,  cen- 
tral institutions  of,  303 

cooperative  banks  of,  306 

establishment  of,  297 


INDEX 


499 


Imperial  Federation  of  Agri- 
cultvtral  Cooperative  So- 
cieties,   Germany,   fail- 
ures in,  304,  305 
membership  of,  1913,  303 
organization    and   purposes 

of,  298 
relations  of,  with  Prussian 
Central         Cooperative 
Bank,  311 
scope  of,  298,  299 

Improvement  Company  for 
England  and  Wales,  159 

India,  British.  See  British 
India. 

Individual  credit,  4 

Instalments,  loans  extin- 
guished by,  17 

Institution  for  the  Encour- 
agement of  Irrigation 
Works  and  Develop- 
ment of  Agriculture, 
Mexico,  201,  202 

Insurance,  old-age,  in  Ger- 
many, 99,  100 

Insurance    companies    in   the 
United  States,  459,  460 
public,  207 

Insurance  institutions  (pri- 
vate) in  Germany,  103, 
104 

Internal  Emigration  Service, 
Sussia,  169 

Xatemational  Agricultural 
Congress,  Budapest, 
1885 

Ireland,   agricultural  popula- 
tion of,  155 
agriculture  in,  440 
Board  of  Public  Works  of, 
153,  154 


Ireland,    Congested    Districts 
Board  of,  154 

cooperative  associations  in, 
461 

Department  of  Agriculture 
and  Technical  Instruc- 
tion of,  154,  155 

economic  conditions  in,  in 
1889,  440 

Estates  Commissioners  of, 
155,  157 

land  legislation  in,  156-158 

long-term  loans  in,  211 

nationalization  of  land  in, 
215 

rural  cooperative  credit  as- 
sociations in,  441,  442 
imsatisfactoiy       progress 
of,  442,  443 

why  no  private  land-credit 
companies  in,  210 

work  of  Sir  Horace  Plun- 
kett  for  cooperation  in, 
440,  447 
Irish   Agricultural   Organiza- 
tion Society,  439,  442 

formation  of,  440 

work  of,  441 
Irish  Church  Act,  1869,  156 
Irish  Homestead,  444 
Irish  Land  Act,  1903,  157 
Istituto    Italiano    di    Credito 
Fondiario,  139 

capital  stock  of,  144,  145 

foxmdation  of,  144 

method     of,     of     granting 
loans,  145 
Italy,   agricultural   credit  in- 
stitutions in,  146,  147 

central  cooperative  institu- 
tions in,  359-363 


soo 


INDEX 


Italy,  cooperative  associations 

iQ,  349,  350 
early   work   in   cooperation 

in,  255 
early   work   in   cooperation 

credit  in,  260 
history   of  land   credit  in, 

136-141 
land-credit   institutions   in, 

219,  220 
legislation    on    cooperative 

credit  in,  349,  350,  353, 

359 
legislation  on  land  credit  in, 

136-140,  146 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
people's  banks  of,  348-354 
present  system  of  land  credit 

in,  136,  13Y,  140-147 
project  for  central  coopera- 
tive bank  in,  363 
rural  credit  societies  in,  354- 

359 
state     aid     to     cooperative 

credit  in,  359-363 
work  of  Luzzatti  in,  347-349 
work  of  Wollemborg  in,  354 

Jamaica,    credit    society    in, 

438 
Japan,  agricultural  conditions 
in,  433 
Central  Association  of  Co- 
operative   Societies    of, 
434,  435 
cooperative      societies      in, 
classes  of,  434 
federations  of,  434,  435 
regulations  for,  434 
early  mutual   aid   societies 
in,  433 


Japan,  land-credit  institutions 
of,  provision  for  sink- 
ing     fund      of,      219, 
220 
land-credit  system  of,  189- 

192 
legislation    on    cooperation 

in,  433,  435 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
modem  cooperative  societies 
in,  433-435 
Java,       Baifieisen       Society 

founded  in,  1904,  438 
Jewish   Agricultural  and  In- 
dustrial   Aid    Society, 
United  States,  218 
efforts  of,  to   establish   co- 
operative     credit     for 
Jewish       farmers       in 
United  States,  451,  452 
Jewish  farm  colonies  in  Pales- 
tine, 414 
Jews,  in  South  America,  455 
in  the  TTnited  States,  colon- 
ies of,  454,  455 
rural    cooperative    credit 
among,  451-455 
in  Western  Canada,  455 
Joint  Agricultural  Board  of 
Trade      for      England, 
Wales,      Ireland      and 
Scotland,  439 
Joint  Board  for  Agricultural 
Organization,     Great 
Britain,  439 
Josseau,    Jean-Baptiste,    324, 
325 
report   of,   on  land   credit, 

112 
syndical  banks  foimded  by, 
333 


INDEX 


601 


Kansas,  application  of  Silesian 
type  of  landsctaft  to, 
226-229 

Kardjew,  411 

Karolyi,  Count  Alexander, 
system  of  rural  credit 
in  Hungary  organized 
by,  371,  372,  457 

Klagenfurt,  early  credit  asso- 
ciation at,  365 

Korea,  189 

Kiir  and  Nemnark,  land- 
schaft  of,  77,  78,  86 

Kurland.     See  Courland. 

Kuttuchuttu  of  British  India, 
428 

Kwango  Ginko.  See  Nippon 
Kwango  Ginko. 

Laborers,  loans  to  in  Trance, 

134,  135 
La  Cooperazione  Rurale,  357 
Land  as  basis  for  bank  loans, 
32 
as  basis  for  cnrrency,  30,  31 
as  basis  for  money,  31 
Land    Bank    of    New    York, 
compared  with.  Central 
Landscbaft  of  Prussia, 
239 
Land   Bank   or   Manufactory 
Scheme,   Massachusetts 
Bay  Province,  29,  30 
provisions   for  organization 

of,  232,  235-237 
purpose  of,  237,  238 
Land  Bank  of  Paris,  113,  114 
Land  Bank  of  Servia,  175 
Land-banks,  Biiring's  schema 
for  establishing,  38-42 
business  of,  in  1912,  146 


Land-banks,  in  American  col- 
onies, 27-30 
in  England,  first  two,  24,  25 
in  Prance,  established  under 
the  law  of  1852,  113 
failure  of,  138,  139 
in  Italy,    at    present    time, 
140,  141 
interest  rates  of,  145 
Istituto  Italiano  di  Credi- 

to  Pondiario,  143-145 
management  of,  141-144 
privileges  of,  144 
rural  business  of,  145 
under  law  of  1866,  137 
under  law  of  1885,  138 
Land    commissions,    Eussian, 

169,  172,  173 
Land  Court  of  Scotland,  151, 

152 
Land  credit,  3 

best    method    of,    for    the 

United  States,  242-244. 

during  Prench  Revolution, 

26,  27 
experiments  in,  in  England 

and  Scotland,  24-26 
first  principles  of,  33 
in  Argentine  EepubHc,  202, 

203 
in  Australia,    193-195 
in  Austria  -  Himgary,    161- 

168,  219 
in  Chile,  203,  205 
in  colonial  America,  27-30 
in  Costa  Bica,  205 
in  Cuba,  206 
in  Europe,  lessons  of,  16 
object  of,  21 
state  aid  to,  16 
in  Finland,  173,  174 


503 


INDEX 


Land  credit,  in  France,  111- 
135,  218 

in  Germany,  34-110,  217 

in  Great  Britain   and  Ire- 
land, 148-160 

in  Italy,  136-147,  219 

in  Japan,  189-192 

in  Mexico,  196-202 

in  New  York,  232-239 

in  New  Zealand,  195,  196 

in  Norway,  184-186 

in  PLilippiaes,  192,  193 

in  Prussia,  26 

in  Soumania,  175 

in  Eussia,  167-174,  218 

in  Servia,  175 

in    Sweden,    181-184,    217, 
218 

in  Uruguay,  205. 

See   also   Kansas,  New 
York,  Ohio,  "Wisconsin. 

organization  of,  16 

principles  of,  and  their  ap- 
plication, 209-244 

SUesian  scheme  for,  in  Kan- 
sas, 226-229 

two  kinds  of  bodies  for,  15 
Land  Credit  Bank  of  Geneva, 

178 
Land-credit    banks,    German, 

94,  95,  105-110 
Land  Credit  Company  of  Sar- 
dinia, 141 
Land     Credit     Institute     at 

Nagy-Szeben,  168 
Land-credit    institutions,    de- 
bentures of,  220-224 

distinguishing    feature    of, 
210 

Barly  object  of,  in  Europe, 
20 


Land-credit  institutions,  gen- 
eral plan  of  administra- 
tion of,  213,  214 
in  Denmark,  179-181,  218 
in  Egypt,  187-189 
in  French  West  Africa,  438 
ia  Switzerland,  176-179,  218 
in  United  States,  history  of, 

preface 
organization  of,  225,  226 
private,    scope    of   business 

of,  214,  215 
privileged     debentures     of, 

223 
public,  classes  benefited  by, 

215 
rules  and  regulations   gov- 
erning, 216,  217 
scope  of  business  of,  215 
reasons  for  existence  of,  210 
sinking  fund  of,  219 
special  privileges  and  state 

aid  to,  11-16 
snmniary  process  of,  for  col- 
lecting claims,  216,  217 
for  examining  titles,  216 
for  protecting  rights,  216 
types  of,  212,  213 
See    also   Landschafts    and 
Land  credit. 
Land-improvement     acts     in 
Great  Britain  and  Ire- 
land, 158-160 
Land-improvement      annuity 
banks,  Germany,  95-97 
Land    Law     (Ireland)     Act, 

1881,   156 
Land  Loan  and  Enfranchise- 
ment Company  for  Eng- 
land,  Wales,   Scotland, 
and  Ireland,  159 


INDEX 


503 


Land   Mortgage   Associations 

Act,  Wisconsin,  229-232 

Land     Mortgage      Bank      of 

Beme,  218 
Land  Mortgage  Bank  of  Nor- 
way, 184 
Landowners'  mortgage  associa- 
tions, Switzerland,  181, 
183 
Land-pnrchase   legislation,  in 
Ireland,   156-158 
in  Egypt,  187 
value  of,  determination  of, 
by   Silesian  landschaft, 
59 
relation  of,  to  loans,  21 
Landschafts,    adaptability    of, 
to  United  States,  226- 
229 
Central,   need   of,    in   Ger- 
many, 88,  89 
Prussian,  89-91 
Danish,  179,  180 
definition  of,  35 
desirability      of,      in      the 
United  States,  242-244 
extinguishing   of  loans   in, 

18,  21 
German,    amortization    in, 
83,  85 
era  of  conversion  in,  82, 

83 
first  organized,  43 
number  and  location  of, 

34,  35 
old  and  new,  35 
old  compulsory,  36 
origin  of,  34-44 
original    type    of    land- 
credit    institution,    34, 
213 


Landschafts,    German,    short- 
comings of,  92,  93 
meaning  of  the  word,  44 
object  of  early,  43 
other  than  Silesian,  condi- 
tion   of,    during    Na- 
poleonic wars,  81,  82 

debentures  of,  88 

new  type  of,  variations 
among,  87 

old  type  of,  credit  and  de- 
bentures of,  79,  80 
defects  of,  80 
management  of,  78,  79 
reforms  in,  82-87 
variations  in,  78 

organization  of,  77 

state  aid  to,  77 
Prussian,  225 
Silesian,  226-228 

accounts  of,  70,  71 

advantages  of,  to  mem- 
bers, 63 

amortization  funds  of,  64, 
70,  75 

bank  of,  56,  58,  67 

bank  fund  of,  70 

bureaus  of,  for  loans  to 
non-members,  56,  57, 
58 

circles  of,  54-56 

condition  of,  in  1912,  74- 
76 

debentures  issued  by,  60- 
62,  71-76 

district  boards  of,  48-51 

executive  council  of,  47, 
48 

general  assembly  of,  51-53 

general  funds  of,  69,  75 

guaranty  fund  of,  70 


1504 


INDEX 


Xandschafts,   Silesian,  liabili- 
ties of  members  of,  in 
case  of  default,  64,  65 
loans  to  non-members  of, 

66,  67 
obligations  of,  58 
obligations    of    borrower 

to,  62,  63 
■organization  of,  45-47 
permanent  committee  of, 

53,  54 
power  of  state  over  funds 

of,  71 
procedure  in  obtaining  a 

loan  from,  58-62 
reports  of,  71 
rights  of  members  of,  63, 

64 
standing    committees    of, 
51 
state  aid  to,  224 
Xands      Improvement      Com- 
pany      for       England, 
Wales     and     Scotland, 
159 
XassaUe,  Ferdinand,  257,  267, 

268 
Xaw,  John,  25,  26 

Company   of  the  West   of, 

250 
influence  of,  on  Biiring,  38 
Xeo  XTTT,  Pope,  357 
Xeo  Xm  (bank),  418 
Xevis,   first   cooperative  bank 
in  America  at,  445.  See 
also  Caisse  Popxdaire. 
Xiechtenstein,  principality  of, 
no  figures  on  coopera- 
tive credit  for,  426 
Xife  insurance  as  security  for 
loans,  206-208,  384,  385 


Xiguria,  Italy,  Agrarian  credit 

institute  of,  362 
Xitera  A  debentures,  69 
Xitera  B  debentures,  73,  74 
Xitera  C  debentures,  69,  70  ^ 
Xitera   D   debentures,   special 

funds  for,  70 
Xivonia,     Eussia,     territorial 
credit  establishment  for, 
174,  218 
Xocal    cooperative    credit    so- 
cieties.    See  Eural  co- 
operative   credit   socie- 
ties. 
Xong-term  credit.    See  Xong- 

term   loans. 
Xong-term  loans,  3,  4 

advantages  of,  for  farmers, 

244 
definition  of,  17 
essential  to  farmers,  211 
favored  by  Eaiffeisen,  287 
in  Germany,  101 
in  United  States,  7,  8 
land-credit  institutions  and, 

210,  212 
length  of,  in  various  coun- 
tries, 211 
not  possible  to  be  made  by 

individuals,    212 
of  Credit  Foncier,  118 
of  Credit   Union   of   Brus- 
sels, 381 
of  French    regional    banks, 

343 
of  French  rural  cooperative 

banks,  340 
of  German  central  cooper- 
ative baiiks,  308 
of  Hungarian  credit  socie- 
ties, 377 


INDEX 


505 


Long-term    loans,    of    Italian 
rural    credit    societies, 
358 
tlirougli      Credit     Agricole 
Mutuel,    France,    132- 
134 
■unrecaUable  debentures  nec- 
essary for,  222,  223 
Longuinine,  S.  F.,  396,  456 
Loreggia  credit  society,  found- 
ing of,  354 
influence  of,  356 
organization  and  operation 
of,  354-356 
Lottery,  in  France,  125,  126 
Louisiana,   acquisition  of,  by 
John    LaVs    Company 
of  the  West,  251 
Ludwigshafen,    grain    seUing 

societies  of,  304 
Limeburg,      organization      of 

landschaft  in,  77,  78 
Luxemburg,     agriculture     in, 
389,   390 
no    cooperative    credit    in, 

389 
state  banks  in,  389 
Luzzatti,  Luigi,  influence  of, 
on  WoUemborg,  354 
originator  of  new  type  of 
credit   association,  260, 
456 
public  career  of,  346 

Maasbracht,  first  credit  so- 
ciety in  Holland 
formed    at,    387 

Mahillon,  385 

Mailath,  George,  163 

Malarc,   A.,  270 

Malthus,  Thomas  Eobert,  269 


"Mandats,"  27 

Marches  of  TJmbria,  credit  in- 
stitute of,  362 
Maria  Theresa,  163 
Massachusetts,    credit   unions 

in,  479 
Massachusetts    Bay,   province: 

of,  land   credit  in,  28,. 

29,  30 
Mechlenburg,  landschaft  of,  82^ 
Meline,  Jules,  amendment  to 

law  of  1884  proposed  by,, 

332 
first    activities    of,    for    co- 
operative credit,  322 
law    of    1899    drafted    by,. 

335 
Meline  law,  or  law  of  1899,. 

335,  336 
MeUaerts,  Father,  Boerenbond 

or  Peasants'  League  of 

Belgium   organized  by,. 

384,   386 
EaifEeisen  bank  founded  by,. 

384 
Merry  del  Val,  Cardinal,  357 
Mexico,  land  mortgage  banks. 

and  promotion  banks  in,. 

196-202 
Midhat  Pasha,  409 
Milcent,      cooperative      bank 

founded  by,  322 
Misericordias,        Portuguese^ 

419,  420 
Mixed  land-credit  banks,  107 
Monaco,    principality    of,    no 

cooperative    credit    in„ 

426 
Monte  dei  Paschi,  140,  141 
Montenegro,  Eaiffeisen  society 

in,  413 


506 


INDEX 


Monti  Frumentarii,  146 

Mortgage  associations,  Dan- 
ish, 179,  180 

Mortgage  Bank  of  Berne, 
177 

Mortgage  Bank  of  Fribourg, 
178,  179 

Mortgage  Bank  of  Spain,  416, 
418 

Mortgage  Bank  of  St.  Gall, 
178 

Mortgage  Bank  of  the  King- 
dom of  Denmark,  180 

Mortgage  Bank  of  Vaud,  177, 
178 

Mortgage    banks    of    Mexico, 
197-199 
of  Switzerland,  176-178 

Mortgage-bond,  definition  of, 
17 

Mortgage  Society  of  Finland, 
174 

Mortgages  .  in  force  under 
Silesian  landschaft  in 
1912,  75 

Moscow  Agricultural  Associa- 
tion, 396,  397 

Moscow  People's  Bank,  402, 
403 

Mutual  Commercial  Exchange 
Bank,  Montreuil  and 
Vincennes,  322 

Mutual  insurance  in  United 
States,  459,  460 

Mutual  savings  banks  in  the 
TJnited    States,    admin- 
istration of,  458 
contrasted    with    European 

People's  banks,  458 
statistics  of,  457 

Mutual  telephone  companies. 


rapid  growth  of,  among 
farmers,  460 

Napoleon  m,  114,  322,  324 

Napoleonic  wars,  effect  of,  on 
German  landschafts,  81, 
82 

National  Agricultural  Credit 
Institute,  Spain,  pro- 
ject for,  419 

National  Bank  of  Egypt,  188 

National  Federation  of  Cath- 
olic Eural  Credit  Socie- 
ties, 357 

National  Federation  of  Hun- 
garian Land  Credit  In- 
stitutions, 167,  168,  377 

National  Federation  of  Eural 
Credit  Societies,  Italy, 
357 

National  Insurance  Society, 
France,  207 

National  Land  Credit  Insti- 
tute for  Small  Land- 
owners of  Himgary, 
166,  167,  377 

National  Loan  Bank,  Sweden, 
182 

National  Small  Holdings  Land 
Mortgage  Institute, 
Hungary,  374 

Neumark.  See  Kiir  and  Neu- 
mark. 

New  England,  early  land 
credit  in,  27,  28 

New  England  Mutual  Life  In- 
surance Co.,  cooperative 
character  of,  459 

New  London  Society  TJnited 
for  Trade  and  Com- 
merce, 29 


INDEX 


507 


New  South  Wales,  194 

New  York,  savings  and  loan 
associations  of,  232-239 

New  York  Land  Bank,  241 
special  privileges  of,  236  . 

New  York  law  on  credit 
unions,  defects  of,  479 

New  York  Life  Insurance  Co., 
cooperative  character 
of,  459 

New  York  Mutual  Life  Insur- 
ance Co.,  cooperative 
character  of,  459 

New  Zealand,  land  credit  in, 
195,  196 
long-term  loans  in,  211 

Nicholson,  Sir  Frederick  A., 
work  of,  for  coopera- 
tive credit  in  India, 
429,  430 

Nicosia,  Cyprus,  Savings 
Bank  of,  413,  414 

Nidhis,  of  British  India,  428 

Nieder-Modau  credit  society, 
failure  of,  304,  305 

Nippon  kwango  ginko,  189, 
190,   191 

Noko  ginko,  Japan,  189-192 

Norrland  fund,  Sweden,  184 

Norway,  collective  buying  in, 
391 
credit  institutions  in,  391 
no  cooperative  credit  socie- 
ties in,  391 
savings     banks     the     chief 
source    of    agricultural 
credit  in,  391 
state  aid  in,  184-186 

Norwegian  Bank  for  Labor- 
ers' Holdings  and 
Dwellings,  391 


Ohio,  savings  and  loan  asso- 
ciations of,  240 

Old-age  insurance  in  Ger- 
many, 99,  100 

Ontario,  cooperative  banks  in, 
446 

Oriental  Colonization  Com- 
pany, 189 

Owen,  Robert,  activities  for 
cooperation,   254 

Oxford  Provident  Building 
and  Loan  Association, 
254 

Palestine,  cooperation  prac- 
ticed by  Jewish  colon- 
ists in,  414 

Paper  money,  based  on  land 
in   French   Revolution, 
26,  27 
idea  of  debentures   evolved 

from,  24 
plans  for  issue  of,  against 
land    in    Massachusetts 
Bay,  28 

Partnerships,       disadvantages 
of,  250 
distinguished   from   cooper- 
ative associations,  248, 
249 

Peasants,  condition  of,  in 
Europe,  14 

Peasants'  Christian  League, 
Holland,  387 

Peasants'  Cooperative  Mort- 
gage Bank,  Holland, 
387 

Peasants'  League  of  Belgium, 
384,  386 

Feasants'  State  Land  Bank, 
Russia,  169-172 


608 


INDEX 


PeequeuT,  321 

Penn,  WilKam,  grant  to,  250 
Pennsylvania,    grant    of,    to 
William  Penn,  250 
land  credit  in,  28 
Pensions  to  retired  employees 
of  Credit  Foncier,  117 
to   Silesian  landschaft  offi- 
cials, 47,  69 
People's  Bank  of  Menton,  323 
People's  Bank  of  Milan,  347, 

348 
People's  banks,  compared  with 
mutual   savings   banks, 
458 
in  Germany,  263-280 
aim  of,  287 
Bureau  of  Exchange  of, 

280 
federation  of,  279 
in  Italy,  classes  reached  by, 
353 
compared    with    Schulze- 
Delitzsch    banks,    348, 
349 
organization  and  manage- 
ment of,  350-352 
origin  of,  347,  348 
relation  of,  to  agriculture, 

353,  354 
scope  of,  352 
statistics  for,  348 
in  Quebec,  449-461 
in  Boumania,  405 
in  United  States,  446 
origia  of,  257 
See     also      Schulze-DeHtzseh 

People's  Banks. 
People's  state  banks  in  Lux- 
emburg, 389 
Perier,  Casimir,  111-113 


Permanent  committee  of  the 
Silesian  landschaft,  53, 
54 

Pesth  Savings  and  Loan  So- 
ciety, 371 

Philippines,  Agrieultu ral 
Bank  of,  192,  103 

Pious  Works  of  Saint  Paul  of 
Turin,  141 

Plunkett,  Sir  Horace,  440, 
441,  457 

Poland,  land-credit  institu- 
tions for  nobles  in,  218 

Pomerania,  landschaft  in,  77, 
78,  81,  85,  86 
public    insurance    company 
founded  in,  207 

Pomeranian  Ritterschaft 

Bank,  104 

Portugal,    misericordias     and 
celleiros  of,  419-421 
modem     agricultural     mu- 
tual  credit   system   of, 
421-426 

Posen,  landschaft  of,  82 

Provincial    Credit  Associa- 
tion for,  83,  84 
public    insurance    company 
founded  in,  207 

Posiios,   Spanish,  415-417 

Potash  Purchasing  Company, 
Germany,  303 

Premiums,  issue  of,  with  de-; 
bentures,      by      Credit 
Eoncier,  125,  126 
by       Mexican       mortgage 
banks,  198 

Prince  Eupert,  251 

Prizes,  issue  of,  with  debai- 
tures,  by  Credit  Fon- 
cier, 125,  126,  218,  222 


INDEX 


509 


Prizes,  by  Mexican  mortgage 

banks,  198 
Productive  credit,  3 
Promotion     banks,     Mexican, 

200,  201 
Proudbon,  321 
Provident  Aid  Bank,  Limoges, 

322 
Provident  societies  for  natives 

in  Tunis,  437,  438 
Provincial  agriciiltural  banks, 

Italy,  361,  362 
Provincial  aid  to  agricultural 
cooperation  in  Austria, 
369 
Provincial  Bank  for  the  Ba- 

silicata,  360 
Provincial  cooperative  banks, 

Germany,  306-309 
Provincial  Credit  Association 
for  the  Grand  Duchy  of 
Posen,  83,  84 
Prussia,  central  landschaft  of, 
89-91 
mortgage  debt  in,  4 
organization  of  land  credit 

in,  26 
origin  of  landschafts  in,  fol- 
lowing    Seven     Tears' 
War,  36 
state  aid  to  cooperation  in, 
300-302,  309 
Prussian  Central  Cooperative 
Bank,  313 
creation  of,  309 
operations  of,  310 
organization  of,  309,  310 
relations  of,  with  other  in- 
stitutions, 311 
statistics    of,    310-311, 
312 


Prussian  Central  Land  Credit 

Company,  108-110 
Public  granaries  in  Japan,  433 
in  Bussia,  401 
in  Servia,  408,  409 
in  Spain.     See  Posiios. 
Pure  land-credit  banks,  107 
"Purge"  for  mortgages,  of  the 
Credit  Foncier,  121 

Quebec,  Caisse  Populaire  of, 
445-449 
cooperative   banks   in,   446, 

450 
law  of  1906  for  cooperative 
associations     in,     449, 
450 

Queensland  (Australia)  land- 
credit  commission,  194, 
195 

Eagu,  Abbot,  322 
Raiffeisen,  Amelia,  290 
Eaiffeisen,  Frederick  William. 
Henry,      compulsory 
audit  favored  by,  303 
contribution  of,  to   cooper- 
ative credit,  294,  295 
early  work  of,  for  coopera- 
tion, 284,  285 
influence  of,  in  France,  325, 
329 
in  Germany,  440 
in  Hungary,  371,  372 
Ufe  and  character  of,  281- 

284 
work    of,    for    cooperation, 
284-286 
Eaiffeisen,  Fassbender  &  Co., 
290 


510 


INDEX 


Eaiffeisen    cooperative    credit 
societies,  agitation  for, 
in  Italy,  354 
collective  purchasing  by,  473 
in  Austria,   366-368 

compared  with  the   Ger- 
man societies,  367 
in  Belgium,  384,  385 
in  Bulgaria,  411 
in  colonies     of     European 

powers,  437 
in  Cyprus,  413,  414 
in  European  Turkey,  413 
in  Germany,    aim    of,    287, 
288 
attempted    affiliation    of, 
with  Imperial  Federa- 
tion, 297,  303 
Central  Agricultural  Loan 
Bank  of,  290,  291,  306, 
308 
collective    purchase     and 

sales  features  of,  317 
foundation  fund  of,  288 
General     Federation     of, 

291 
how  they  comply  with  the 

law,  314 
mortgages  taken  by,  104 
no   dividends   distributed 

by,  287 
no    salaries    allowed   offi- 
cers of,  287 
objects  of,  289 
reserves     of,     indivisible, 
287 
in  Holland,  387 

in  Himgaiy,  372,  379 
in  Ireland,  441,  442 
in  Montenegro,  413 
in  Kussia,  396,  397 


Eaiffeisen    cooperative   credit 

societies,  in  Servia,  407 
in  Spain,  417,  418 
in  Switzerland,  392 
objects  of,  478 
scope  and  spirit  of,  292 
why     best     for     American 

farmers,  477 
Eaiffeisen  system,  adoption  of, 

in  Italy,  355 
beginnings  of,  285,  286 
Central   Agricultural   Loan 

Bank  and,  290,  291 
centralization  of,  290 
collective  purchases  by,  289, 

290 
differences  between  Schulze- 

Delitzsch     banks     and, 

286-288 
failures  in, -304 
General  Federation  of  Eural 

Cooperative       Societies 

and,  290,  291 
growth  of,  286 
organization    and    adminis- 
tration of,  288-290 
provincial    unions    in,    291, 

292 
reasons  for  success  of,  292- 

295 
Eayneri,  Charles,  activities  of, 

in      cooperation,      322, 

323 
Eeal-estate  credit,  use  of,  7, 

8.       See    also    Land 

credit. 
Eegional  banks,  474 
of  Algeria,  437 
of  Tunis,  437 
See     also    Eural    regional 

banks. 


INDEX 


511 


Eegistrars  in  British  India, 
■wide  discretion  allowed 
to,  431 

Eenckhoff,  W.,  259 

Eent-Charge  Bank  of  the 
Grand  Duchy  of  Hesse- 
Darmstadt,  206 

Eent-charge  banks,  Germany, 
97-100 

Eibet,  436 

Eice  granaries,  Japanese,  433 

Eitterschaft,  definition  of, 
35 

Eobinson,  Leonard,  activities 
of,  for  rural  cooperative 
credit  in  the  United 
States,  452,  453 

Eochedale,  Equitable  Pio- 
neers of,  254,  255 

Eoman  Catholic  Church,  atti- 
tude of,  toward  cooper- 
ative credit,  357,  358 
rural    cooperation    in   Hol- 
land aided  by,  386 

Eostand,  Eugene,  322,  345 

Eothschild,  Baron,  414 

Eomnania,   cooperative  credit 
in,  405,  406 
state  aid  to,  406 
landschafts    established    in, 

in  1873,  174 
Eural  Bank  of,  174 

Eoyal  Bank,  of  John  Law, 
25 

Eoyal    Bank,    Scotland,    270, 

271 
Eoyal    Credit    Institute    for 

Silesia,  74 
Eoyer,  Charles  Edward,  22,  36, 

112,  324 
Eural  Bank  of  Eoumania,  174 


Eural   cooperative    banks,    in 
France,  law  of  1894  on, 
332 
membership  of,  333,  338 
relation  of,  to  syndicats, 

332,  333,  337 
statutory  provisions  relat- 
ing to,  338 
in  the  United  States,  Jew- 
ish, 452-454 
Eural   cooperative    credit   so- 
cieties,   advantages    of, 
473 
characteristics  of,  461,  462 
classified  by  presence  or  ab- 
sence of  shares,  463 
collective  purchase,  sale  and 
manufacture    by,    472, 
473 
distribution    of   profits    of, 

472 
federations  of,  474 
finances  of,  463,  464 
in  Austria,  366-368 
central  banks  for,  367 
rapid  development  of,  368 
state   and  provincial  aid 

to,  368-370 
statistics   of   failures    of, 
370 
in  Belgium,  385,  386 
in  Bulgaria,  411 
in  Denmark,  389,  390 
iu  Egypt,  436,  437 
in  England  and  Wales,  444, 

445 
in  France,  324, 332-336,  338- 

341 
in  Germany,  in  1912,  286 
in  Holland,  387 

central  banks  of,  387,  388 


513 


INDEX 


Rural  cooperative  credit  socie- 
ties,   in    Ireland,    441, 
442,  443 
in  Italy,  146,  147 
distribution  of,  359 
first,   354-356 
growth  of,  356,  357 
loans  of,  358 
statistics  for,  358,  359 
in  Spain,  history  of,  417 
organization    and    opera- 
tion of,  418 
statistics  -of  1913,  418 
syndical  character  of,  417 
in  Switzerland,  392,  393 
length  of  loans  of,  472 
members    not    all    farmers, 

462 
not  benevolent  institutions, 

466 
procedure  in  formation  and 
development  of,  474-479 
similarity  of  aU  systems  of, 

in  Europe,  473 
sources  of  funds  of,  463 
special  privileges  of,  464 
See  also  Baifieisen  societies, 
Baiffeisen  system,   and 
names  of  various  coim.- 
tries. 
Rural  cooperative  savings  and 
loan  societies,  Russian. 
8ee  Cooperative  savings 
and  loan  societies. 
Rural     cooperative      systems, 
European,-   outline    of, 
473,  474 
in  Germany,  469-472 
Rural    credits    movement    in 
United  States,  preface, 
object  of,  9 


Rural     regional     banks,      in 
France,  credit  extended 
by,  336 
first  formed,  337 
growth  of,  337 
powers  of,  335 
provisions  for,  in  Meline 

law,  335,  336 
relations    of,    with   local 

banks,  341 
right  of,  to  issue  bonds, 

344 
state  aid  to,  336,  343 
statistics  for.  1912,  342 
in  Germany,  inspection  of, 
313 
operation  of,  307,  308 
organization  of,  307 
statistics  of,  308,  309 
organization    and    manage- 
ment of,  341,  342 
powers  of,  341 
Russia,   agrarian  troubles  in, 
171 
artel  in,  396 
Bank  of,  400 
central  credit  banks  in,  402, 

403 
Courland,  174 
cooperative   credit   societies 

of,  398,  399 
early  cooperative  loan  and 
savings  societies  in,  396 
emancipation    of    serfs    in, 

169,  170 
Esthonia,  174 

extent  of  cooperation  in,  395 
federation     of     cooperative 
credit  societies  in,  399, 
400 
Finland,  173,  174 


INDEX 


513 


Eussia,  land-credit  system  in, 

218 
land  projects  in,  168-170 
legislation    on    cooperative 

credit  in,  397,  401,  402 
Livonia,  174 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
Peasants'  State  Land  Bank 

of,  169-173 
rural  population  of,  393 
small  credit  institutions  of, 

397,  398 
state  aid  in,  215,  396,  397, 

401,  402 

Saghalien,  189 

San     Marino,     [Republic     of, 

Italian   cooperat ive 

banks  available  for,  426 

Sardinia,    Casse    Ademprivili 

of,  361,  362 
Savings  and  Aid  Bank,  Bez- 

stercze,  Hungary,  371 
Savings  and  loan  associations, 
general  methods  of,  240 
nature    of   membership    of, 

239 
not  adapted  to  farmers,  241 
of  New    York,    absence    of 
rural  element  in,  239 
Bank  of  New  York  and, 

235-239 
condition  of,  in  1914,  234, 

235 
statutory      powers       and 
methods  of,  232-234 
of  Ohio,  240 
reasons    for    soimdness    of, 

242 
Eussian,  396 
Savings  Bank  of  Bologna,  141 


Savings  Bank  of  Grand  Duchy 

of  Luxemburg,  389 
Savings  Bank  of  Milan,  141 
Savings  Bank  of  Nicosia,  Cy- 
prus, 413,  414 
Savings  Bank  of  Verona,  141 
Savings  Bank  of  Victoria,  194 
Savings     banks,     extinguish- 
ment of  loans  by,  18 
French,  333 

possible  aids  to  rural  co- 
operative credit,  344 
German,  102,  103 
Say,  Leon,  322 

Schlosshalde,  first  Swiss  rural 
cooperative    credit    so- 
ciety in,  392 
Schoelinde,  early  credit  asso- 
ciation at,  365 
Schulze-Delitzsch,  456 
death  and  reputation  of,  268 
early  life  of,  263-265 
ideas     of,     regarding     sys- 

temization,  306 
influence  of,  in  France,  324, 
329 
on  Luzzatti,  347 
on  Eaiffeisen,  259,  285 
principles  of,  in  Eussia,  397 
theory    of,    of    cooperation, 

256-258 
work    of,    for    cooperation, 
265-268 
Schulze-Delitzsch      People's 
Banks,     classes     inter- 
ested in,  274 
compared      with      people's 

banks  in  Italy,  348 
decentralization  of,  279,  280 
differences  between  Eaiffei- 
sen  system  and,  286-288 


514 


INDEX 


Schulze-Delitzsch      People's 
Banks,  in  Austria,  365, 
366 
in  Belgium,  383 
in  Germany,  263-280 

opposition  of,  to  Prussian 
Central   Cooperative 
Bank,  311 
statistics  of,  1911,  319, 320 
in  Hungary,  371 
in  Eussia,  398 
in  Switzerland,  391 
organization  and  operation 

of,  275-279 
plan  of,  272-274 
See  also  People's  banks. 
Scotcli  banks,  270,  271 
Scotcb     credit.       See     Cash 

credit. 
Scotland,     Agricultural     Or- 
ganization   Society   of, 
445 
Board    of    Agriculture    of, 

151-153 
cooperative  associations  of, 

445 
Land  Court  of,  151,  152 
land-credit  experiments  in, 

25 
landholder  in,  151,  152 
relation    between    landlord 

and  tenant  in,  151 
small  holder  in,  151,  152 
Scottish  Agricultural  Organi- 
zation Society,  439,  445 
Scottish    Drainage    and    Im- 
provement      Company, 
159 
Scrip,   issue  of,   on   land,  in 

United  States,  31 
Sebastian,  King,  420 


Sequestration,  217 
Servia,  central  banks  in,  408 
cooperative   banks   in,   407, 

408 
general  union  of  cooperative 

credit  societies  in,  408 
land  credit  in,  175 
public  granaries  of,  408,  409 
Servian  Federation  at  Zagrab, 

379 
Settlement   commission,   Ger- 
many, 97 
Settlers'  Board  of  New  South 

Wales,  194 
Seven  Tears'  War,  36 

results  of,  37 
Short-term  credit.    See  Short- 
term  loans. 
Short-term  loans,  3,  4,  8 
in  Germany,  101 
of  Credit  Foncier,  118 
of  French  rural  cooperative 

■    banks,  340 
of  Hungarian  credit   socie- 
ties, 377 
of  Italian   rural  credit   so- 
cieties, 358 
of  regional  bank  of  France, 
343 
Shubrah-el-Namlah,  rural  co- 
operative credit  society 
at,  437 
Siberia,  colonization  of,  169 
Silesia,   area    and   population 
of,  45 
first  landschaft  created  in, 

43 
land-credit  system  of.    See 

Landschaft,  Silesian. 
public    insurance    company 
founded  in,  207 


INDEX 


515 


Silesian      landschaft.        iS^ee 

LandscHaft,  Silesian. 
Sinking   fund  of   land-credit 

institutions,  219,  220 
"Small     credit    institutions," 

Eussia,  397,  398 
Small    Holdings    and    Allot- 
ments Act,  1908,  Great 
Britain,  148-151 
Socialism,     cooperation     and, 
253,  254,  373 
origin  of,  253 
Societe     Credit     Immobilier, 

France,  134,  135 
Societe    du    Credit    Agricole, 

325,   326,   327 
Soule,  323 

Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepren- 
eurs de  Batiment,  118 
connection     of,     witt     the 
Credit     Foncier,     128, 
129 
establishment  of,  128 
functions  of,  128,  129 
methods  of,  of  lending,  129, 

130 
security  demanded  by,  130 
South   Australia,   state   bank 

of,  193 
South     Seas,    monopolies    of 

companies  over,   250 
Spain,  banks  of,  418 
early  efforts  at  cooperation 

in,  255 
legislation    on    cooperative 

credit  in,  419 
Mortgage    Bank    of,    416, 

418 
need     of    credit    in,    415, 

416 
positos  of,  415-417 


Spain,    project    for    National 
Agricultural     Credit 
Institute  in,  419 
rural  cooperative  credit  so- 
cieties in,  417,  418 
Special   privileges,    grant   of, 
13,  14 
to  agricultural  associations 

in  Spain,  417,  419 
to  Central  Cooperative  Bank 

of  Bulgaria,  413 
to  cooperative  credit  socie- 
ties in  Belgium,  382 
to  land    credit    in    France, 

111, 224 
to   land-credit    institutions, 

11,  224 
See  also  State  aid. 
Speculation,      prohibited      in 
Silesian  landschaft,   68 
State  Advances  Act  of  South 

Australia,  193 

State  aid,  attitude  of  Schulze- 

Delitzsch  banks  toward, 

274 

effect  of,  on  cooperation,  261 

for    agricultural    banks    in 

France,  260 
for  agricultural  cooperation 
in  Austria,  368-370 
in  France,  333-336 
for    agricultural    credit    in 

£o;imania,  406 
for    cooperative    credit,    in 
British  India,  428 
in  Denmark,   389 
in  England    and    Wales, 

443 
in  Finland,  404 
in  France,  343,  344,  469 
in  Germany,  309-311 


616 


INDEX 


State  aid  for  cooperative  cred- 
it, in  Holland,  387,388 
in  Hungary,  373 

bad  effect  of,  378 
in  Ireland,  442,  443 
in  Italy,  359-363 
in  Prussia,  300-302,  309 
in  Eoumania,  406 
in  Eussia,  396,  397,  401, 

402 
in  Spain,  419 
in  Tunis,  437 
for    home    colonization    in 
Finland,   173 
in  New  Zealand,  195 
for  land-credit  institutions, 
224 
conditions      calling     for, 

224,  225 
in  Egypt,  188 
in  Europe,  11,  13,  14,  15 
in  France,  111,  113 
in  Japan,  191 
in  Norway,   184-186 
in  Eussia,  215 
for    land    improvement    in 

France,  336 
in  Great  Britain  and  Ire- 
land, 158-160 
in  Sweden,  183,  184 
in  organization  of  German 

landschafts,  77 
opposition    of    Schulze-De- 

litzsch  to,  257 
to  Agrarian    Credit    Insti- 
tute of  Liguria,  362 
to  agricultural  credit  insti- 
tution   of   Marches    of 
Umbria,  362 
to  Boden-Kredit      Institut, 
Hungary,  165 


State  aid,  to  cooperative  soci- 
eties in  Germany,  300- 
302 

to  Hungarian  Centre,  373- 
375 

to  Irish  Agricultural  Or- 
ganization Society,  441 

to  land-credit  institutions 
in  Germany,  93 

to  mutual  credit  system  in 
Algeria,  437 

to  provincial  agricultural 
banks  in  Italy,  361 

to  Provincial  Bank  for  the 
Basilicata,  360 

to  rural  cooperative  credit 
societies  in  Belgium, 
385 

to  Victor    Emanuel    Bank, 
360,  361 
State   Bank    of    South   Aus- 
tralia, 193 
State   banks    of    Luxemburg, 

389 
State  invalidity  and  old  age 
insurance    institutions, 
Germany,  99,  100 
von  Steiger,  392 
Storks,  Sir  Henry,  429 
Strassburg,  grain-selling  asso- 
ciations of,  304 
Sweden,  amortization  in,  19 

cooperative  credit  in, 
391 

cooperative  law  of  1911  in, 
391 

General  Mortgage  Bank  of, 
182,  183 

government  appropriations 
for  land  improvement 
in,  184 


INDEX 


517 


Sweden,  land-credit  system  of, 
211,  218 
landowners'  mortgage  asso- 
ciations   of,    181,    182, 
183 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
Swedish     General     Mortgage 

Bank,  182,  183,  218 
Swiss    Union    of    Eaiffeisen 

Banks,   392 
Switzerland,  banks  in,  393 
cooperative  purcliase  of  cat- 
tle in,  393,  394 
credit  unions  in,  382 
land-credit   institutions   in, 

176-179 
land-credit  system  of,  218 
long-term  loans  in,  211 
people's  banks  in,  391 
rural    cooperative    societies 
in,  392,  393 
Syndical  associations,  France, 

119 
Syndical  banks,  France,  333. 
See  also  Eegional  agri- 
cultural banks. 
Syndicalism,     260,     262,  328, 
460 
adopted  by  rural  cooperative 

credit  system,  385 
beginning  of,  in  agriculture, 
328 
Syndicats,  Belgian,  385 
French,  320 

cooperative     credit     and, 

332,  333 
distinguished   from   asso- 
ciations, 330 
formation  of,  under  law 

of  1884,  330,  331 
growth  of,  333 


Syndicats,  French,  in  coopera- 
tive systems,  473 
law  of  1884  on,  329 
objects  of,  331 
scope  of,  331,  332 
Portuguese,  422 

Taiwan  Bank,  Japan,  189 

Taxation,  excessive,  in  United 
States,  224 

Telephone  companies,  mutual, 
in  the  United  States, 
460 

Territorial  Bank  of  Cuba,  206 

Territorial  Credit  Establish- 
ment for  Baltic  Prov- 
inces, 174 

Texas,  rural  credit  unions  in, 
479 

Thurgau,  Switzerland,  co- 
operative cattle  buying 
in,  393,  394 

Torrens  system,  121,  216 

Traber,  392,  457 

Trade  imions,   advent  of  co- 
operation with,  254 
EngUsh,  254 

Treves,  imion  of,  300 
banks  of,  306 

Tunis,   cooperative  banks   in, 
437 
provident  societies  for  na- 
tives of,  437,  438 

Turkey,  European,  Eeifieisen 
society  in,  413 

Union,  misuse  of  word,  480 
Union  cooperative  banks,  Ger- 
many, 306-309 
Unions,   cooperative,  in   Ger- 
many, 299,  300 


518 


INDEX 


TTnions,   cooperative,   in   Ger- 
many,  compulsory  out- 
side audit  for,  302,  303 
source  of  income  of,  302 
state  aid  to,  300-302 

in  cooperative  systems,  4Y3, 
4Y4 
Unlimited  liability,  why  safe, 

293 
United     States,     absence     of 
peasant  class  in,  224 

agricultural  credit  in,  5-8 

agricultural  population  of, 
contrasted  with  Euro- 
pean peasantry,  14,  15 

agricultural  wealth  in,  9 

agriculture  in,  6,  7,  9 

area  of  farms  in,  6 

building  and  loan  associa- 
tions in,  447,  457 

cooperative  credit  among 
Jewish  farmers  of,  451, 
452 

credit  institutions  in,  com- 
pared with  those  of  Eu- 
rope, 15 

defects  of  credit  system  in, 
8 

desirability  of  landschafts 
in,  242-244 

excessive  taxation  in,  224 

farmers'  debt  of  1910  in,  5-8 

Federal  Eeserve  Act  of,  8,  9 

first  appearance  of  cooper- 
ative credit  in,  254 

general  agitation  of  rural 
credit  idea  in,  452 

history  of  cooperative  credit 
in,  preface 

inadequacy  of  credit  facili- 
ties in,  5,  212 


United   States,   interest   rates 
in,  5 
Jewish  Agricultural  and  In- 
dustrial Aid  Society  of, 
218 
Jewish  agricultural  colonies 

in,  454 
Jewish  population  of,  451 
Jewish     rural     cooperative 

banks  in,  452-455 
lack    of    rural    cooperative 

credit  system  in,  460 
legislation    on    cooperative 
credit  required  in,  479, 
480 
'  mortgage  debt  in,  4 
mutual    savings    banks    of, 
administration   of,   458 
contrasted  with  European 

people's  banks,  458 
number  and  business  of, 
457 
mutual  insurance  in,  459, 460 
mutual  telephone  companies 

in,  460 
people's  banks  in,  446 
rural     cooperative     institu- 
tions in,  460 
rural  credits  movem.ent  in, 

preface 
supremacy  of,  in  cooperative 
finance,  459 
in  mutual  banking,  459 
"Urbarians,"  163 
Uruguay,  land  credit  in,  205 
Utrecht    Central  Bank,   Hol- 
land, 388 

Victor  Emanuel  Bank,  360 
Victoria,   Savings  Bank  Act 
of,  194 


INDEX 


519 


Yidal,  321 

Vienna,  early  credit  associa- 
tion at,  365 

Viger,  Albert,  332,  335  ' 

Vranovo,  first  cooperative 
bank  in  Servia  at,  407 

Waldeck-Eonsseau,  331 
Wales,       Farmers'       Central 

Trading       Board       of, 

439 
See  also  Great  Britain. 
Warsaw     Cooperative     Bank, 

402 
Webster,  Daniel,  252 
West  Prussia,  landsehaft  in, 

Y7,  78,  81,  82,  85,  86 
public    insurance    company 

founded  in,  207 
Western  Australia,  Bank  of, 

193,  194 
von     Westerode,     de     Wolff, 

438 
Windhoek  credit  society,  Ger- 
man Southwest  Africa, 

438 
Wisconsin,  cooperative  credit 

associations  in,  479 


Wisconsin,  Land  Mortgage  As- 
sociations Act  of,  229- 
232 
Wolff,  Dr.  Charles,  372 
Wolff,  Henry  W.,  441,  446 
account  of  the  Westerwald 

by,  258 
influence  of,  in  Ireland,  441 
opinion    of,    on    Canadian 

people's  banks,  446 
work    of,     for    cooperative 
credit  in  British  India, 
429,  430 
Wollemborg,  Leone,  371 
public  career  of,  346 
work  of,  357 
Wolowski,  Louis,  112 
Wiirttemberg,  union  of,  300 
banks  of,  306 

Zamora,    Spain,    rural    credit 
societies  in,  418 

Zemstvo  people's  banks,  Eus- 
sia,  401,  402 

Ziller,  456 
Federation    of    Schulze-De- 
litzsch  Societies  of  Aus- 
tria founded  by,  366 


(1)