Skip to main content

Full text of "Deregulation of electric utility firms : an assessment of the cost effects of complete deregulation vs. deregulation of generation only"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 
A         BOOKSTACKS 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/deregulationofel905prim 


!'■-■  L- 


FACULTY  WORKING 

PAPER  NO.  905 


HIE  LIBRARY  QEItie 

DEC  2  81982 

^E^TYOF.LL.NO.S 


Deregulation  of  E!ectric  Utility  Firms:  An  Assessment 
of  the  Cost  Effects  of  Complete  Deregulation  vs. 
Deregulation  of  Generation  Only 

Walter  J:  Primeaux,  Jr. 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois,  Urbana-Champaign 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  No.  905 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
September  1982 


Deregulation  of  Electric  Utility  Firms: 
An  Assessment  of  the  Cost  Effects  of  Complete 
Deregulation  vs.  Deregulation  of  Generation  Only 


Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  Professor 
Department  of  Business  Administration 


Abstract 

During  recent  years,  concerns  about  the  real  effectiveness  of 
electric  utility  regulation  have  led  to  a  number  of  policy  prescriptions, 
including  total  deregulation  and  deregulation  of  only  the  generating 
function.   Proponents  of  deregulation  of  only  generation  function  argue 
that  distribution  is  a  natural  monopoly  and  should  not  be  subjected  to 
competition;  they  allege,  without  statistical  data,  that  direct  competi- 
tion would  result  in  higher  distribution  costs. 

This  paper  presents  an  examination  of  the  question  of  whether 
competition  in  distribution  would  actually  lead  to  higher  costs.   Data 
from  real  markets,  where  direct  electric  utility  competition  actually 
exists,  show  that  competition  in  distribution  does  not  lead  to  higher 
costs.   The  main  conclusion  is  that  policy  prescriptions,  which  only 
recommend  deregulation  of  generation  only,  are  too  limited  in  scope. 


Deregulation  of  Electric  Utility  Firms: 

An  Assessment  of  the  Cost  Effects  of  Complete 

Deregulation  vs.  Deregulation  of  Generation  Only 

by  Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr. 
University  of  Illinois  -  Urbana-Champaign 


INTRODUCTION 

Concerns  about  real  effectiveness  of  electric  utility  regulation 
are  not  unique  to  recent  times;  indeed,  the  literature  reveals  that 
through  time,  a  number  of  authors  have  expressed  serious  criticism  of 
the  existing  regulatory  process  (e.g.,  Behling,  1938,  Stigler  & 
Friedland,  1962,  Moore,  1970). 

Stigler  and  Friedland  (1962)  did  not  find  any  significance  effects 
of  regulation  of  electric  utilities.   Moore's  (1970)  conclusions 
included  the  observation  that  regulation  has  not  reduced  electricity 
prices  more  than  5  percent  and  probably  less  than  that  amount. 

C.  Moore  (1975)  found  that  regulation  had  a  perverse  effect 
because  it  actually  caused  higher  consumer  prices.   Jackson  (1969) 
found  that  regulation  did  not  succeed  in  reducing  residential  rates  in 
1940  and  1950,  but  was  effective  in  1960.   One  unusual  empirical  study 
supporting  the  public  interest  theory  of  regulation,  where  regulators 
maximize  social  welfare,  is  by  Nelson  (1982).   The  overall  results  of 
these  studies  show  little  support  for  regulation  as  an  effective  insti- 
tution and  most  authors  express  concern  about  economic  performance  in 
an  environment  of  commission  regulation. 

Another  series  of  early  studies  examined,  in  a  rigorous  way,  the 
structure  of  the  electric  utility  industry.   These  studies  examined 
the  profit  and  price  effects  of  combination  utilities  (those  selling 


-2- 

both  gas  and  electricity)  compared  with  straight  utilities  (those 
selling  only  gas  or  electricity) .   These  studies  are  typified  by  the 
work  of  Mann  (1970)  and  Collins  (1973),  although  a  number  of  other  eco- 
nomists have  also  investigated  these  situations.   Results  of  the  indi- 
vidual studies  in  this  group  differed  to  some  extent  in  their 
assessments  and  conclusions  concerning  the  effects  of  the  accumulation 
of  very  strong  monopoly  power  in  the  case  of  combination  utilities. 
Yet,  as  a  group,  they  developed  rigorous  statistical  analyses  and 
raised  the  first  serious  questions  concerning  problems  with  the  present 
structure  of  the  electric  utility  industry.   The  studies  within  this 
group  individually  made  policy  recommendations  regarding  the  value  of 
maintaining  the  existing  structure  compared  with  benefits  of  rivalry  to 
be  gained  from  splitting  up  combination  companies  into  competing 
straight  gas  and  electric  companies. 

In  the  1970' s,  a  number  of  empirical  studies  examined  the 
Averch- Johnson  overcapitalization  effect  under  a  regulatory  constraint. 
A  number  of  authors  engaged  in  these  investigations  but  these  studies 
are  typified  by  the  work  of  Petersen  (1976)  and  Needy  (1976).   These 
kinds  of  studies  generally  showed  that  regulation  caused  firms  to 
employ  excessive  amounts  of  capital  stock. 

The  above  studies  all  raise  some  serious  questions  about  the  effect 
of  direct  electric  utility  regulation  and  they  demonstrate  serious  con- 
cern about  the  outcome  achieved  under  the  existing  regulatory  process. 

In  1968,  I  began  research  dealing  with  cities  with  two  competing 
electric  utilitv  firms.   This  research  is  similar  in  spirit  to  that 


-3- 

examining  the  competitive  effects  of  combination  gas-electric  utili- 
ties.  The  essential  difference  is  that  those  combination  studies 
attempted  to  determine  whether  the  beneficial  effects  of  competition 
were  surpressed  if  a  single  monopoly  sold  both  electricity  and  natural 
gas  within  a  given  city,  compared  with  situations  where  these  two  ser- 
vices were  provided  by  two  separate  companies.   In  contrast,  my  com- 
petitive research  has  examined  the  effect  of  direct  head-to-head  com- 
petition where  two  electric  companies  operate  in  a  given  city  and 
customers  have  a  choice  of  being  served  by  one  company  or  the  other. 
Bellamy  (1981)  wrote  a  case  study  of  such  competition  in  Lubbock,  Texas 
and  Primeaux  (1974b)  presented  a  case  study  of  Sikeston,  Missouri. 

Through  the  years  my  research  has  examined  a  number  of  aspects  of 
the  business  to  determine  the  effects  of  the  direct  competition  between 
firms  alleged  to  be  natural  monopolists.   This  research  has  extended  to 
average  costs  levels,  capacity  utilization,  price  rigidity,  case  studies 
of  cities  in  which  competition  has  existed  over  a  long  period  of  time, 
and  an  examination  of  circumstances  which  have  recently  led  to  a  decline 
of  direct  competition  in  a  few  cities  (Primeaux,  1974a,  1974b,  1975a, 
1975,  1982).   The  lower  average  costs  from  direct  competition  were  later 
confirmed  by  Hollas  and  Herring  (1982),  using  a  slightly  modified 
sample. 

My  research  was  the  first  to  examine  the  natural  monopoly  theory 
under  competitive  conditions,  using  rigorous  statistical  methods. 
Hellman's  (1972)  work  was  in  process  but  unpublished  when  my  direct 
electric  competition  research  program  was  begun,  although  this  was 
unknown  to  me.   Even  so,  Hellman's  research  is  largely  composed  of  case 


-4- 

studies  and  examinations  of  the  institutional  arrangements  surrounding 
the  direct  competition  where  it  existed  or  has  existed  In  history.   His 
research,  in  any  case,  is  interesting  but  It  Is  totally  void  of  sta- 
tistical analyses. 

Moore  (1976)  and  Ramsey  (1976)  later  discussed  some  favorable 
aspects  of  direct  electric  utility  competition.   These  particular  stu- 
dies largely  rely  on  previously  published  work  and  do  not  develop  or 
present  any  useful  new  data  for  examination;  yet,  they  are  of  interest 
to  students  of  regulation.   An  earlier  study  by  Seidel  (1969), 
discussed  the  favorable  benefits  of  fringe  area  rivalry,  where  com- 
petition exists  only  at  and  around  the  borders  of  service  areas. 
Seidel' s  work  is  interested  in  assessing  competitive  benefits  but  it  is 
confined  to  limited  competition. 

More  recently,  Schuler  and  Hobbs  have  written  a  number  of  papers 
using  computer  simulation  to  assess  the  effects  of  direct  utility  com- 
petition.  Their  results  generally  show  beneficial  effects  from  the 
direct  competition.   Some  of  this  important  work  is  presented  in 
Schuler  and  Hobbs  (1981)  and  Hobbs  and  Schuler  (1981,  1982).   One 
important  difference  between  the  Hobbs  and  Schuler  research  and  the 
research  undertaken  by  the  previous  Primeaux  studies  is  that  their  work 
is  based  on  simulation  of  engineering  data,  using  analyses  which  do  not 
allow  for  any  X-efficiency  as  found  by  Primeaux  (1977).   Their  research 
constitutes  another  approach  to  assessing  the  impact  of  direct  com- 
petition; yet,  the  realism  of  differential  efficiency  is  not  captured 
by  their  analyses. 


-5- 

Seidel  (1981)  explains  that  the  Primeaux  research  is  the  only  work 
actually  using  direct  operating  data  (under  competitive  conditions)  to 
examine  performance  of  electric  utility  firms.   The  point  is  that  the 
effects  of  the  competition  changes  the  position  of  the  cost  curves 
through  X-efficiency  (Primeaux  1977),  and  these  effects  would  possibly 
impact  upon  other  performance  measures,  such  as  consumer  prices,  for 
example. 

Plummer  seems  to  be  calling  for  additional  research  of  the  direct 

electric  utility  competition  question  in  the  following  quote  concerning 

my  research. 

If  it  could  be  demonstrated  that  such  direct  competi- 
tion did  not  lead  to  major  inefficiencies,  then  the 
whole  argument  for  treating  distribution  as  a  natural 
monopoly  could  come  tumbling  down...  (see  Primeaux, 
1975)  (from:   Plummer,  1981). 

This  study  examines  the  effect  of  direct  competition  on  the  costs 

of  firms  which  generate  and  distribute  power  compared  with  firms  which 

only  distribute  power  but  do  not  generate.  The  results  show  that  the 

direct  competition  does  not  lead  to  major  inefficiencies.   It  is  not 

necessary,  therefore,  that  electricity  distribution  be  treated  as  a 

natural  monopoly. 

PURPOSES  OF  THE  STUDY 
The  above  discussion  has  shown  that  there  has  been  much  concern 
expressed  concerning  the  existing  regulatory  process  as  well  as  some 
questions  raised  about  the  present  structure  of  the  electric  utility 
industry.   These  concerns  have  now  reached  the  stage  where  policy  makers 
are  seriously  considering  various  alternatives  and  options  which  could 


-6- 

lead  to  drastic  changes  in  structure  and  regulation  of  the  industry 
(Seidel  1981). 

The  Edison  Electric  Institute  (1982)  and  various  papers  in  Shaker 
and  Steffy  (1976)  explain  that  one  possible  regulatory  reform  is  the 
deregulation  of  generation  only  with  regulatory  control  maintained  over 
distribution.   This,  however,  is  not  clearly  the  best  policy  choice 
(Seidel,  1981,  Plummer,  1981).   The  superiority  of  this  choice  compared 
with  total  deregulation  has  not  been  previously  established. 

Actually,  the  Primeaux  (1975a)  study  contained  both  firms  which 
bought  their  power  requirements  for  sale  to  consumers  as  well  as  firms 
which  generated  power  for  sale  to  consumers.   Consequently,  the  sample 
lends  itself  to  an  important  new  analysis  of  the  difference  between 
firms  which  only  distribute  power  compared  with  those  which  generate 
and  distribute.   An  analysis  of  these  results  permit  a  determination  of 
the  differential  cost  effects  of  each  phase  of  operation.   These  results 
provide  the  assessment  of  any  inefficiency,  mentioned  earlier,  which 
may  be  caused  by  the  direct  competition  which  Plummer  (1981)  considers 
to  be  very  important.   Moreover,  an  evaluation  of  these  results  provide 
some  insight  into  the  comparative  benefit  of  deregulating  the  genera- 
tion function  only  vs.  the  benefit  to  be  gained  from  deregulating  both 
the  distribution  and  generation  functions.   These  results  are  useful 
because  the  data  are  from  competitive  markets,  so  competitive  effects 
are  actually  reflected  in  the  data.   Since  competition  will  be  a  result 
of  deregulation,  these  data  tend  to  show  what  would  happen  if  deregula- 
tion of  each  function  took  place  and  direct  competition  ensued. 


-7- 

METHOD 

Nature  of  the  Sample 

The  procedure  followed  for  selecting  the  sample  for  the  statistical 
analyses  was  very  similar  to  that  used  in  Primeaux  (1975a,  1977,  1981). 
The  directly  competitive  situations  actually  consist  of  cases  where  a 
publicly-owned  (municipally-owned  firm  operating  in  a  single  city) 
competes  with  a  privately-owned  firm  (operating  in  several  cities). 
The  privately-owned  firms  do  not  allocate  operating  data  to  the  indivi- 
dual cities  they  serve;  moreover,  their  competitive  area  constitutes 
only  a  relatively  small  part  of  their  overall  operation,  so  the  effect 
of  the  direct  competition  upon  these  multi  city  firms  is  not  very 
significant.   Consequently,  the  data  of  privately-owned  firms  is  of  no 
value  to  this  study,  even  if  they  were  available.   This  complication  is 
elaborated  upon  in  detail  in  Primeaux  (1975a,  1977,  1978). 

Because  of  the  problem  mentioned  above,  the  sample  was  limited  to 
the  municipally-owned  firms  actually  facing  direct  competition  and  they 
were  compared  with  a  sub  sample  of  municipally-owned  firms  which  are 
monopolists.   The  cities  included  in  the  sample  are  presented  in  Tables 
1A  and  IB  in  the  appendix.   Municipally-owned  firms  do  not  suffer  from 
the  data  problems  mentioned  above.   The  sample  of  matched  firms  was 
selected  from  those  presented  in  Primeaux  (1975a,  1977,  1978)  so  as  to 
avoid  statistical  problems  mentioned  in  those  studies. 

The  sample  consisted  of  firm  data  from  1964-1968,  composed  of  five 
years  of  pooled  cross  section-time  series  data,  as  in  Primeaux  (1975a). 
The  appropriate  Chow  tests  to  confirm  the  acceptability  of  the  pooling 
process  are  presented  in  the  appendix.   More  recent  data  were  not  used 


-8- 

for  two  reasons.   First,  as  Primeaux  (1932)  indicates,  the  sample  of 
available  firms  has  declined  in  more  recent  years,  so  the  choice  was 
made  to  use  more  older  data  instead  of  less  more  current  data.   Second, 
more  recent  data  would  have  been  affected,  to  some  extent,  by  the  change 
in  energy  supply  characteristics  which  took  place  in  the  1970's.   To 
some  extent,  those  changes  could  have  distorted  operating  results  with 
effects  which  would  not  be  indicative  of  meaningful  differences  upon 
which  to  make  policy  judgments.   In  addition  to  the  previous  justifica- 
tion for  using  the  older  data,  a  previous  study  has  explained  that  the 
period  around  1967  represented  rather  settled  conditions  for  making 
comparisons  (Mann  and  Mikesell,  1971).   All  in  all,  extreme  care  was 
taken  in  the  sample  selecting  procedure  and  process  to  preserve  the 
integrity  of  the  statistical  results. 

STATISTICAL  ANALYSIS 

The  statistical  analysis,  model,  and  variables  used  in  this  study 
follow  closely  those  in  Primeaux  (1975a). 

The  statistical  procedure  was  ordinary  least  squares  multiple 
regression  analysis  with  equations  in  the  form 


Y  =  A  +  B.X.  +  B.X.  +  B.X,  X 

11    2  2    3  3       n 


where: 

Y  is  the  estimated  average  cost  of  the  firm 

X.  sales  of  electricity,  in  million  of  kilowatt-hours 

X„  generating  capacity  utilization  rate 

X  steam  electric  fuel  cost 


-9- 

X,  hydroelectric  fuel  cost 

Xs  consumption  per  commercial  and  industrial  customer 

X,  consumption  per  residential  customer 
o 

X7  cost  of  purchased  power,  per  kwh. 

XQ  market  density  factor 

o 

X  internal  combustion-generation  dummy 

X  Alabama  dummy 

X  Indiana  dummy 

X  Iowa  dummy 

X  Maryland  dummy 

X...  Missouri  dummy 

X  _  Ohio  dummy 

X  ,  Oregon  dummy 
lo 

X  7  South  Carolina  dummy 

X  0  South  Dakota  dummy 
lo 

X  q  Texas  dummy 

X„„  Nebraska  dummy 

X„   Alaska  dummy 

X  „  competition  dummy  variable 

X9„  interaction  variable  (X„„  with  X.. ) 
An  explanation  of  data  sources  and  variable  specification  are  provided 
in  the  appendix. 

The  only  difference  between  the  above  variables  and  those  used  in 
Primeaux  (1975a)  is  that  in  the  earlier  study  the  purchased  power 
variable  was  specified  differently.   As  indicated  in  the  appendix,  the 
purchased  power  variable  in  this  study  is  the  actual  cost  of  purchased 


-10- 

power  per  KWH  purchased;  Che  1975  study  used  the  proportion  of  purchased 
kilowatt-hours  of  power  to  total  kilowatt-hour  sales.   To  assess  the 
impact  of  this  change,  the  1975  equation  was  specified  with  this  new 
purchased  power  variable.   When  the  equation  was  run  with  the  changed 
purchased  power  variable,  the  competition  dummy  variable  was  changed 
from  -1.5155  mills  per  million  kwh  in  the  1975  study  to  -1.353  mills 
per  million  KWH.   So  the  results  are  more  conservative  with  the  modified 
specification.   No  other  important  differences  occurred.   Since  purchased 
power  is  quite  important  in  the  following  analysis,  the  decision  was 
made  to  use  the  variable  reflecting  actual  purchased  power  costs,  instead 
of  the  1975  specification. 

Although  the  remaining  variables  in  this  study  are  identical  to 
those  in  the  1975  study,  there  is  a  significant  change  in  the  procedure 
used  to  develop  the  cost  equations.   As  in  the  earlier  study,  Michigan 
dummy  variables  are  omitted  to  avoid  the  statistical  problems  which 
occur  when  all  dummy  variables  are  included  in  equations.   Primeaux 
(1975a)  combined  firms  which  generated  and  distributed  power  with  firms 
which  purchased  their  energy  requirements  and  only  distributed  power  to 
consumers.   The  cost  equations  presented  in  that  study,  therefore,  were 
quite  composite  in  nature  and  any  differential  impact  of  competition 
upon  the  individual  functions  of  the  electric  utility  business  was  not 
assessed. 

The  procedure  used  here  represents  a  refinement,  which  should  make 
the  results  more  useful  for  public  policy  purposes  and  should  provide 
some  additional  information  toward  answering  the  questions  mentioned 
earlier  which  were  raised  by  Plummer  (1981). 

The  sample  for  this  study  was  divided  into  two  types  of  firms;  that 
is  one  sub  set  consisted  of  those  firms  which  generated  and  distributed 


-11- 

power.   The  second  consisted  of  firms  which  only  purchased  their  require- 
ments and  did  not  generate  any  power.   The  division  was  made  because  it 
was  thought  that  this  approach  would  permit  a  better  assessment  of  the 
effects  of  duplicate  facilities  to  engage  in  direct  electric  utility 
competition.   The  cost  impact  of  duplication  of  facilities  caused  by 
direct  competition  probably  does  not  fall  equally  upon  firms  which 
generate  and  distribute  and  those  which  do  not  generate  and  purchase 
all  of  their  power  requirements.   Indeed,  strong  presumptions  about  the 
nature  of  the  differential  cost  impact  are  behind  the  arguments  presented 
by  those  who  advocate  deregulating  only  the  generating  function  and 
requiring  the  distribution  function  to  remain  as  a  regulated  monopoly. 

The  following  analysis  permits  an  assessment  of  the  cost  effects  of 
complete  deregulation  of  electric  utilities  after  direct  competition 
ensued. 

Table  1  presents  the  average  cost  equation  for  firms  in  the  sample 
which  generate  and  distribute  power.   Many  of  these  firms  did  buy  some 
power  but  they  were  not  solely  dependent  on  purchased  power.   Indeed, 
the  industry  data  show  that  many  firms,  both  publicly  and  privately 
owned,  purchase  power  for  resale,  even  though  they  also  generate  with 
their  own  facilities. 

Table  2  presents  the  average  cost  equation  for  non-generating  firms. 
The  following  discussion  relates  to  the  coefficients  presented  in  both 
Tables  1  and  2. 

The  coefficient  of  the  sales  variable  (X  )  reveals  that  economies 
of  scale  accrued  to  the  generating  and  distributing  companies;  however, 
diseconomies  of  scale  accrued  to  the  non-generating  companies,  indicating 


■12- 


TABLE  1 


POOLED  REGRESSION 
FIRMS  GENERATING  AND  DISTRIBUTING 


VARIABLE 


X. 


10 
11 

12 
13 
14 
15 

16 

17 

18 

19 
c20 

21 
^22 

23 


Sales  of  Electricity 

(millions  of  kilowatt-hours) 

Generating  Capacity  Utilization 

Steam-Electric  Fuel  Cost 

Hydroelectric  Fuel  Cost 

Consumption  per  Commercial  and 

Industrial  Customer 

Consumption  per  Residential  Customer 

Cost  of  Purchased  Power 

Market  Density  Factor 

Internal  Combustion  Generation  Dummy 

Alabama  Dummy 

Indiana  Dummy 

Iowa  Dummy 

Maryland  Dummy 

Missouri  Dummy 

Ohio  Dummy 

Oregon  Dummy 

South  Carolina  Dummy 

South  Dakota  Dummy 

Texas  Dummy 

Nebraska  Dummy 

Alaska  Dummy 

Competition  Dummy 

X  *  CD  Interaction  Variable 


PARTIAL 
REGRESSION    STANDARD 
COEFFICIENT    ERROR 


-.002 


.000* 


-.059 

.014* 

-.045 

.020** 

-.002 

.002 

-.032 

.004* 

-.213 

.067* 

-.013 

.004* 

-.190 

.269 

-.744 

.468 

2.030 

.566* 

2.039 

.561* 

2.731 

.796* 

2.129 

.355* 

.994 

.468** 

4.595 

1.055* 

4.636 

.762* 

3.688 

.546* 

-.952 

.774 

.977 

.683 

1.471 

.337* 

.007 

.001* 

Summary  Statistic 

N  (degrees  of  freedom  plus  number  of  variables)  172 

R2   .8151 

Constant  23.287  (mills) 

Standard  error  of  estimate  1.3476  (mills) 

Source:   Derived  from  pooled  data  for  the  competitive  and  noncompetitive 
utilities  in  Table  1A  of  Appendix. 


*Significant  at  1  percent  level. 

**Signif icant  at  5  percent  level. 

***Signif icant  at  10  percent  level. 


-13- 


TABLE  2 


POOLED  REGRESSION 
NON-GENERATING  FIRMS  ONLY 


VARIABLE 


c10 

'16 

:22 

^23 


Sales  of  Electricity 

(millions  of  kilowatt-hours) 

Consumption  per  Commercial  and 

Industrial  Customer 

Consumption  per  Residential  Customer 

Cost  of  Purchased  Power 

Market  Density  Factor 

Alabama  Dummy 

Maryland  Dummy 

Missouri  Dummy 

Ohio  Dummy 

Oregon  Dummy 

South  Carolina  Dummy 

Competition  Dummy 

X  *  CD  Interaction  Variable 


PARTIAL 
REGRESSION    STANDARD 
COEFFICIENT    ERROR 


,012 


.003* 


-.014 

.003* 

-.244 

.065* 

.690 

.363*** 

1.867 

.489* 

4.583 

2.581*** 

3.008 

2.268 

-.761 

.709 

1.897 

1.371 

■3.302 

3.645 

-.644 

1.233 

1.065 

.916 

-.009 

.007 

Summary  Statistic 

N  (degrees  of  freedom  plus  number  of  variables)  52 

T~   .9908 

Constant  13.166  (mills) 

Standard  error  of  estimate  .4255  (mills) 

Source:   Derived  from  pooled  data  for  the  competitive  and  noncompetitive 
utilities  in  Table  1A  of  Appendix. 


*Significant  at  1  percent  level. 

**Signif icant  at  5  percent  level. 

***Signif icant  at  10  percent  level. 


-14- 

that  their  average  costs  increased  as  their  sales  levels  increased. 

The  market  density  variable  (XQ),  indicates  that  average  costs  decreased 

o 

as  the  number  of  customers  per  square  mile  increased,  reflecting  some 

tendency  for  adverse  pressure  to  occur  on  average  costs  of  non-generating 

firms.   This  same  pressure,  however,  did  not  seem  to  exist  for  generating 

and  distributing  firms  because  the  X  variable  is  not  statistically 

o 

significant  at  the  10  percent  level. 

Another  interesting  result  shown  in  Tables  1  and  2  is  the  coefficient 
on  the  purchased  power  variable  (X7).   While  this  coefficient  is  nega- 
tive and  statistically  significant  (at  the  one  percent  level)  for  firms 
which  generate  and  distribute,  it  is  positive  and  statistically  signi- 
ficant at  the  ten  percent  level  for  firms  which  only  distribute  power. 
This  difference,  of  course,  occurs  because  of  the  relative  importance 
of  purchased  power  to  firms  of  each  type. 

The  mean  cost  of  purchased  power  to  the  non-generating  companies 
was  $5.96  per  1000  KWH  while  the  average  price  paid  by  firms  which 
generated  and  distributed  was  $10. 41  per  1000  KWH.   Part  of  the  explana- 
tion for  the  differences  in  the  price  of  purchased  power  between  the 
two  groups  of  firms  has  to  be  found  in  the  fact  that  the  companies  which 
buy  all  of  their  requirements  are  probably  influenced  to  follow  that 
strategy,  to  some  extent,  by  the  fact  that  they  are  able  to  buy  at  lower 
prices.   If  purchased  power  were  unattractively  priced  to  them,  they 
would  begin  to  generate  their  requirements. 

In  addition  to  the  differences  mentioned  above,  the  following  dif- 
ferences between  the  Primeaux  (1975a)  study  and  the  equations  presented 
in  Table  1  should  be  mentioned.   The  1975  study  presented  positive  and 


-15- 

statistically  significant  coefficients  on  the  steam  electric  fuel  cost 
variable,  the  hydroelectric  fuel  cost  variable,  and  the  internal  com- 
bustion fuel  cost  variable.   Equation  1  shows  a  negative  and  statisti- 
cally significant  sign  on  the  steam  electric  fuel  cost  variable,  and 
negative  but  insignificant  signs  on  the  hydroelectric  and  internal  com- 
bustion fuel  variables. 

Table  1  shows  that  for  firms  generating  and  distributing  power  the 
competition  dummy  variable  is  negative  and  shows  that  the  average  cost 
curve  is  shifted  downward  by  1.471  mills  per  million  KWH,  because  of 
the  direct  rivalry.   This  variable  is  significant  at  the  one  percent 
level.   The  interaction  variable  of  the  competitive  dummy  with  the 
variable  X  shows  the  slope  of  the  cost  curve  does  change  with  direct 
competition.   It,  too,  is  significant  at  the  one  percent  level. 

The  essential  fact  is  that  the  magnitude  of  the  downward  shift  in 
Table  1  was  quite  similar  to  that  presented  in  the  1975  equation 
(Primeaux  1975).   That  equation  presented  a  downward  shift  effect  of 
1.5155  mills  per  million  kilowatt-hours  sales.   That  equation,  too, 
presented  a  positive  interaction  variable  with  sales,  indicating  that 
the  slope  of  the  average  cost  function  became  steeper,  as  sales 
increased.   Together,  the  results  presented  here  indicate  that  direct 
competition  does  cause  lower  average  costs  for  firms  which  generate  and 
distribute  power  after  controlling  for  a  large  number  of  cost  and  demand 
variables;  however,  after  reaching  210  million  kilowatt  annual  sales, 
monopoly  firms  which  generate  and  distribute  power  operate  at  lower 
costs  than  their  competitive  counterparts.   These  results  are  con- 
sistent and  similar  with  those  presented  in  Primeaux  (1975).   Although 
the  equation  presented  above  is  the  appropriate  specification,  Table  2C 
in  the  appendix  presents  this  equation  after  excluding  the  interaction 


-lb- 


variable  with  Che  variable  X  (X  *CD).   The  results  are  consistent  with 
those  presented  above. 

Perhaps  the  most  interest  result  from  Table  2  is  also  the  com- 
petition dummy  variable  and  its  interactioin  variable  with  sales  volume. 
This  variable  shows  that  when  scale,  density  effects,  purchased  power 
as  well  as  a  large  number  of  other  key  demand  and  operating  charac- 
teristics and  state  differences  are  all  controlled  for,  that  competitive 
non-generating  firms  did  not  have  higher  costs  than  their  monopoly 
counterparts.   The  competitive  dummy  variable  coefficient  is,  indeed, 
positive,  indicating  that  there  is  upward  pressure  on  average  costs 
when  direct  competition  exists;  yet,  the  difference  is  not  statistically 
significant  at  the  ten  percent  level.   So  the  effect  is  unimportant. 
Moreover,  the  interaction  variable  is  also  statistically  insignificant, 
so  direct  competition  does  not  cause  these  distribution  firms  to  operate 
at  higher  average  costs.   The  equation  discussed  here  is  the  appropriate 
specification.   Table  2D  in  the  appendix  presents  the  same  equation  after 
excluding  X  *CD.   The  results  are  consistent  with  those  presented  above. 

The  reader  is  reminded  that  the  above  discussion  does  not  present 
data  or  results  for  firms  which  only  generate  power  and  do  not  perform 
the  distribution  function.   It  is  not  possible  to  develop  analyses  to 
examine  the  effect  of  competition  on  the  generation  function  only 
because  there  are  no  firms  facing  direct  competition  which  do  not 
distribute  power.   Nevertheless,  the  extension  of  these  results  to  the 
deregulation  scenarios  discussed  above  does  not  seem  to  be  unreasonable. 

CONCLUSIONS 
The  above  results  mean  that  firms  which  only  distribute  power  do 
not  have  higher  costs  under  competition  than  under  monopoly;  conse- 
quently, concern  expressed  by  those  who  advocate  deregulating  the 


-17- 

generating  function  but  not  the  distribution  function,  because  of 
important  losses  in  economies  of  scale,  seem  to  be  unfounded.   Even 
though  monopoly  distribution  firms  may  have  the  capability  of  operating 
at  lower  costs  than  competitive  distribution  firms,  that  result  was  not 
achieved.   It  is  the  X-inef f iciency  which  sets  in,  in  a  monopoly  market 
structure,  which  offsets  the  technical  losses  caused  by  the  direct  com- 
petition.  This  kind  of  situation  is  discussed  in  detail  in  Primeaux 
(1977). 

Consistent  with  the  Primeaux  (1975a)  study,  these  results  show  that 
firms  which  distribute  and  generate,  do  enjoy  substantial  performance 
improvement  when  subjected  to  direct  competition. 

Since  this  analysis  employs  real  data  from  real  markets,  where 
competition  already  exists  (or  does  not  exist  in  the  case  of  the 
monopolists) ,  the  findings  are  useful  for  public  policy  consideration. 
The  results  show  that  complete  deregulation  seems  to  be  practical 
because  firms  only  distributing  power,  in  a  competitive  market  struc- 
ture, did  not  incur  higher  average  costs  than  their  monopoly  counter- 
parts. 

The  advantage  of  following  complete  deregulation  for  firms  which 
generate  and  distribute  is  that  there  are  cost  economies  through 
improved  X-eff iciency  (Primeaux  1975a).   The  advantage  of  deregulating 
firms  which  only  distribute  is  because  they  incur  no  higher  costs  than 
monopolists,  when  they  face  competition.   If  both  groups  are  completely 
deregulated  it  would  then  be  possible  to  have  price  competition  in 
residential,  commercial  and  industrial  service,  without  concern  for  the 
arbitrary  regulatory  process  of  rate  of  return  regulation  or  rate  making, 


-18- 

The  market  mechanism  can  automatically  perform  the  regulatory  function, 
as  it  does  in  most  other  businesses. 

The  expected  outcome  from  direct  competition  would  be  that  the 
rivalry  would  force  the  firms  to  become  more  efficient  and  operate  at 
lower  costs;  this  fact,  along  with  the  competitive  price  rivalry,  would 
provide  consumers  with  lower  prices.   The  lower  prices  would  be  possible 
because  of  the  elimination  of  inefficiency  and  any  economic  profits 
which  may  exist  under  the  present  arrangement. 


-19- 


REFERENCES 

B.  N.  Behling,  1938.   Competition  and  Monopoly  in  Public  Utility 
Industries.   The  University  of  Illinois,  Urbana. 

William  H.  Collins,  1973.   "Comparative  Performance  of  Combinations 
and  Separately  Managed  Electric  Utilities,"  The  Southern  Economic 
Journal. 

Edison  Electric  Institute,  1982.   Alternative  Models  of  Electric 
Power  Deregulation,  Washington,  Economics  Division,  May. 

B.  F.  Hobbs  and  Richard  E.  Schuler,  1981.   "Estimating  the  Consequence 
of  Competition  in  the  Distribution  of  Electricity — An  Application 
of  Location  Theory,"  presented  to  the  Twenty-eighth  Annual  North 
American  Meeting  of  the  Regional  Science  Association,  Montreal, 
Canada,  November. 

B.  F.  Hobbs  and  Richard  E.  Schuler,  1982.   "A  Spatial  Linear  Program- 
ming Analysis  of  the  Deregulation  of  Electricity  Generation," 
presented  at  the  Institute  of  Management  Sciences  Operations  Re- 
search Society  of  America,  Detroit,  April. 

Daniel  R.  Hollas  and  Robert  S.  Herren,  1982.   "An  Estimation  of  the 
Deadweight  and  X-Efficiency  Losses  in  the  Municipal  Electric 
Industry,"  Journal  of  Economics  and  Business,  in  press. 

David  H.  Huettner  and  John  H.  Landon,  1978.  "Electric  Utilities: 
Scale  Economics  and  Diseconomies,"  Southern  Economic  Journal, 
Vol.  44,  No.  4,  April. 

Richard  Hellman,  1972.   Government  Competition  in  the  Electric  Utility 
Industry,  New  York,  Praeger  Publishers. 

R.  Jackson,  1969.  "Regulation  and  Electric  Utility  Rate  Levels," 
Land  Economics,  Vol.  XLV,  August. 

William  Kent.   Mechanical  Engineers'  Handbook,  vol.  1,  Power  ed.  J.  Kenneth 
Salisbury,  12th  ed. ,  John  Wiley,  1950. 

Patrick  C.  Mann,  1970.   "The  Impact  of  Competition  in  the  Supply  of 

Electricity,"  Quarterly  Review  of  Economics  and  Business,  Vol.  10, 
Winter. 

Patrick  C.  Mann  and  J.  L.  Mikesell.   "Tax  Payments  and  Electric  Utility 
Prices,"  The  Southern  Economic  Journal,  vol.  38,  July  1971. 

Edward  J.  Mitchell,  et.  al. ,  1975.   Toward  Economy  in  Electric  Power, 
Washington,  American  Enterprise  Institute. 


-20- 


C.  J.  Moore,  1975.   "Has  Electricity  Regulation  Resulted  In  Higher 
Prices?   An  Econometric  Evaluation  Using  A  Calibrated  Regulation 
Input  Variable,"  Economic  Inquiry,  Vol.  XIII,  No.  2,  June. 

Thomas  G.  Moore,  1970.   "The  Effectiveness  of  Regulation  of  Electric 
Utility  Prices,"  Southern  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  XXXVI,  April. 

Thomas  G.  Moore,  197b.   "Effects  of  Regulation  on  Electric  Power 

Companies,"  in  Shaker  and  Steffy  (eds.).   Electric  Power  Reform: 

The  Alternative  for  Michigan,  Ann  Arbor.   The  University  of  Michigan. 

Charles  W.  Needy,  1976.  "Social  Cost  of  the  A-J-W  Output  Distortion," 
Southern  Economic  Journal,  Vol.  42,  January. 

Randy  A.  Nelson,  1982.   "An  Empirical  Test  of  the  Ramsey  Theory  and 
Stigler-Peltzman  Theory  of  Public  Utility  Pricing,"  Economic 
Inquiry,  Vol.  XX,  April. 

James  L.  Plumraer,  1981.   "Scenarios  for  Deregulation  of  Electric 
Utilities,"  Mioeo,  November,  EPRI. 

H.  Craig  Petersen,  1976.  "The  Effect  of  'Fair  Value'  Rate  Base  Valua- 
tion in  Electric  Utility  Regulation,"  Journal  of  Finance,  Vol.  31, 
December. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1974a.   "A  Reexamination  of  the  Kinky 

Oligopoly  Demand  Curve,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Vol.  82, 
No.  4,  July-August. 

Walter  J.  Priuieaux,  Jr.,  1974b.   "A  Duopoly  in  Electricity:   Competi- 
tion In  A  'Natural  Monopoly',"  Quarterly  Review  of  Economics  and 
Business,  Vol.  14,  No.  2,  Summer. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1975a.   "A  Reexamination  of  the  Monopoly 
Market  Structure  for  Electric  Utilities,"  in  Promoting  Competi- 
tion in  Regulated  Markets,  Washington,  The  Brookings  Institution. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1975b.   "The  Decline  in  Electric  Utility 
Competition,"  Land  Economics,  Vol.  LI,  No.  2,  May. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1976.   "Electric  Utility  Competition  is 
Feasible,"  in  Shaker  and  Steffy  (eds.),  Electric  Power  Reform: 
The  Alternative  For  Michigan,  Ann  Arbor,  The  University  of 
Michigan. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1977.   "An  Assessment  of  X-Efftciency  Gained 
Through  Competition,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  Vol.  LIX, 
No.  1,  February. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1973.   "The  Effect  of  Competition  on  Capacity 
Utilization  in  the  Electric  Utility  Industry,"  Economic  Inquiry, 
Vol.  XVI,  No.  2,  April. 


-21- 


Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1979.  "Some  Problems  With  Natural  Monopoly," 
The  Antitrust  Bulletin:  Journal  of  American  and  Foreign  Antitrust 
and  Trade  Regulation,  Vol.  XXIV,  No.  1,  Spring. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1981.   "An  Assessment  of  the  Effect  of  Compe- 
tition on  Adversity-Intensity,"  Economic  Inquiry,  Vol.  XIX, 
October. 

Walter  J.  Primeaux,  Jr.,  1982.   An  Examination  of  Direct  Electric 
Utility  Competition:   Some  Perspectives  on  the  Natural  Monopoly 
Myth  (under  review  for  publication  by  a  University  press) . 

James  B.  Ramsey,  et.  al. ,  1976.   "Government  Power,  Regulation,  and 
Markets,"  in  Shaker  and  Steffy  (eds.),  Electric  Power  Reform: 
The  Alternatives  for  Michigan,  Ann  Arbor,  The  University  of 
Michigan. 

Marque  Seidel,  1969.   "The  Margins  of  Spatial  Monopoly,"  Journal  of 
Regional  Science,  Vol.  9,  August. 

Marque  Seidel,  1981.   Pennsylvania  Electric  Efficiency  Scoping  Study, 
Harrisburgh,  PA,  mimeo. 

R.  E.  Schuler  and  B.  F.  Hobbs,  1981a.   "The  Consequences  of  Alternative 
Organizations  of  the  Electric  Utility  Industry,"  presented  at  1981 
meeting  of  the  American  Economic  Association,  December. 

William  H.  Shaker  and  Wilbert  Steffy,  1976.   Electric  Power  Reform: 
The  Alternative  for  Michigan,  Ann  Arbor,  The  University  of 
Michigan. 

G.  Stigler  and  Claire  Friedland,  1962.   "What  Can  Regulators  Regulate?" 
Journal  of  Law  and  Economics,  Vol.  5. 

Statistics  of  Publicly  Owned  Electric  Utilities  in  the  United  States, 
Washington,  U.S.  Department  of  Energy,  various  years. 

Typical  Electric  Bills,  Washington,  U.S.  Department  of  Energy,  various 
years. 

Steam  Electric  Plant  Factors,  National  Coal  Association,  various  years. 

Area  Measurement  Reports,  U.S.  Department  of  Commerce,  various  years. 


D/112 


APPENDIX 

Table    1A 

Cities    in    the    Sample   with   Generation 

Duopolies  Years   of    Data 


Anchorage,   Alaska  1964-1968  5 

Fort   Wayne,    Indiana  1964-1968  5 

Maquoketa,    Iowa  1965-1968  4 

Hagerstown,    Maryland  1964-1968  5 

Allegan,    Michigan  1964-1967  4 

Dowagiac,    Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Ferrysburg,    Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Traverse   City,    Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Zeeland,    Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Kennett,    Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Poplar    Bluff,    Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Trenton,    Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Lincoln,    Nebraska  1964-1965  2 

Cleveland,    Ohio  1964-1968  5 

Columbus,    Ohio  1964-1968  5 

Piqua,    Ohio  1964-1968  5 

Sioux   Falls,    South  Dakota  1964-1968  5 

Garland,    Texas  1964-1968  5 

85 

Monopolies  Years  of  Data  N 

Richmond,  Indiana  1964-1968  5 

Algona,  Iowa  1965-1968  4 

Niles,  Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Wyandotte,  Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Hillsdale,  Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Lansing,  Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Sturgis,  Michigan  1964-1968  5 

Petosky,  Michigan  1964-1963  5 

Carthage,  Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Columbia,  Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Marshall,  Missouri  1964-1968  5 

Omaha,  Nebraska  1964-1965  2 

Springfield,  Illinois  1964-1968  5 

Anderson,  Indiana*  1964  1 

Logansport,  Indiana  1964-1968  5 

Eugene,  Oregon  1964-1968  5 

Watertown,  South  Dakota  1964-1968  5 

Springfield,  Missouri  1964-1968  5 

San  Antonio,  Texas  1964-1968  _5 

87 

*Anderson  ceased  to  generate  in  1965. 


Table  2B 


Cities  in  the  Sample  Without  Generation 


Duopolies 

Bessemer,  Alabama 
Tarrant  City,  Alabama 
Bay  City,  Michigan 
Springfield,  Oregon 
Greer,  South  Carolina 


Years   of  Data 

1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1966-1968 


N 

5 
5 
5 
5 
_3_ 
23 


Monopolies 

Florence,  Alabama 
Scottsboro,  Alabama 
Bristol,  Virginia* 
Rolla,  Missouri 
Greenwood,  South  Carolina 
Anderson,  Indiana** 


Years   of   Data 

1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1964-1968 
1965-1963 


N 

5 
5 
5 
5 
5 
4 
29 


*This  is  a  matched  firm  for  Maryland;  so  in  the  data,  it  is  considered 
to  be  a  Maryland  firm. 


**Anderson  generated  in  1964  and  ceased  generation  in  1965. 


TABLE  2C 

FOOLED  REGRESSION 

FIRMS  GENERATING  AND  DISTRIBUTING 

(X*CD  interaction  variable  excluded) 


VARIABLE 


PARTIAL 

REGRESSION 

COEFFICIENT 


STANDARD 
ERROR 


>-, 
■■n 
7 

X8 
X9 

Xll 

X12 

x  3 

X14 
X1S 

x16 

Jl8 

19 

X20 

x21 

X22 


Sales  of  Electricity 

(millions  of  kilowatt-hours) 
Generating  Capacity  Utilization 
Steam-Electric  Fuel  Cost 
Hydroelectric  Fuel  Cost 
Consumption  per  Commercial  and 

Industrial  Customer 
Consumption  per  Residential  Customer 
Cost  of  Purchased  Power 
Market  Density  Factor 
Internal  Combustion  Generation  Dummy 
Indiana  Dummy 
Iowa  Dummy 
Maryland  Dummy 
Missouri  Dummy 
Ohio  Dummy 
Oregon  Dummy 
South  Dakota  Dummy 
Texas  Dummy 
Nebraska  Dummy 
Alaska  Dummy 
Competition  Dummy 


-.0U2 


.000* 


-.050 

.014* 

-.023 

.021 

-.022 

-.022 

-.033 

.004* 

-.178 

.071* 

-.016 

.004* 

-.422 

.282 

-.493 

.496 

1.387 

.585* 

2.159 

.597* 

2.565 

.848* 

2.109 

.378* 

-.107 

.456 

4.209 

1.121* 

4.591 

.812* 

3.170 

.571* 

-.721 

.824 

1.513 

.718** 

-.890 

.326* 

Summary  Statistic 

N  (degrees  of  freedom  plus  number  of  variables)  172 

T2  .7896 

Constant  22.657  (mills) 

Standard  error  of  estimate  1.4373  (mills) 

Source:   Derived  from  pooled  data  for  the  competitive  and  noncompetitive 
utilities  in  Table  1A  of  Appendix. 


*Significant  at  1  percent  level 

**Signif icant  at  5  percent  level 

***Signif icant  at  10  percent  level 


TABLE  2D 

POOLED  REGRESSION 

NON  GENERATING  FIRMS  ONLY 

(X  *CD  interaction  variable  excluded) 


VARIABLE 


X 


10 
13 
14 

16 
17 

"22 


Sales  of  Electricity 
Consumption  per  Commercial  and 

Industrial  Customer 
Consumption  per  Residential  Customer 
Cost  of  Purchased  Power 
Market  Density  Factor 
Alabama  Dummy 
Maryland  Dummy 
Missouri  Dummy 
Ohio  Dummy 
Oregon  Dummy 
South  Carolina  Dummy 
Competition  Dummy 


PARTIAL 

REGRESSION 

STANDARD 

COEFFICIENT 

ERROR 

.011 

.003* 

-.012 

.002* 

-.228 

.064* 

.589 

.357*** 

-1.700 

.474* 

-5.348 

2.531** 

-3.968 

2.157*** 

-.914 

.705 

1.227 

1.277 

-5.123 

3.381 

-.970 

1.216 

.373 

.744 

Summary  Statistic 

N  (degrees  of  freedom  plus  number  of  variables)  52 

R"2  .9907 

Constant  13.976  (mills) 

Standard  error  of  estimate  .4289  (mills) 

Source:   Derived  from  pooled  data  for  the  competitive  and  noncompetitive 
utilities  in  Table  1A  of  Appendix. 


*Significant  at  1  percent  level 

**Signif icant  at  5  percent  level 

***Signif icant  at  10  percent  level 


CHOW  TESTS 

To  ascertain  whether  it  was  statistically  justified  to  pool  the 
time  series  data,  it  was  necessary  to  determine  whether  the  parameters 
had  shifted  during  the  five-year  time  period  covered  by  the  data.   The 
statistical  procedure  involved  computing  a  separate  regression  for  each 
of  the  five  years  and  then  applying  an  analysis  of  variance  test  (Chow 
test).   This  procedure  was  followed  for  two  different  operations. 
First,  regression  equations  including  all  firms  in  the  sample  were  run; 
that  is  both  the  firms  which  did  not  generate  and  those  which  did 
generate  power  were  combined  in  the  same  equations.   Second,  the  test 
was  run  only  for  firms  which  generated  power.   These  tests  are  presented 
in  the  following  two  tables. 

The  tables  show  that  the  hypothesis  of  unshifted  parameters  cannot 
be  rejected,  since  the  calculated  F  value,  in  each  table,  is  less  than 
the  appropriate  table  value.   These  results  reveal  that  each  year  can 
be  treated  as  a  separate  observation. 

It  was  not  possible  to  perform  the  same  test  for  firms  which  did 
not  generate  power,  because  there  were  insufficient  degrees  of  freedom 
to  run  the  necessary  series  of  equations.   Nevertheless,  this  step  does 
not  seem  to  be  necessary  since  these  firms  were  included  in  the  first 
test  and  excluded  in  the  second  and  no  shift  in  parameters  was  indicated 
in  either  case. 


CHOW  TEST 

INCLUDES  FIRMS  WHICH  ONLY  DISTRIBUTE  POWER 
AS  WELL  AS  FIRMS  WHICH  GENERATE  AND  DISTRIBUTE 


Source  of  Regression 

Std.  Error 
of  Estimate 

D.F. 

K 

DF+K 

MSE1 

Statistics 

SSR2 

Pooled  Regression 

1.5957 

200 

24 

224 

2.546 

509.2 

1964  Regression 

1.9756 

21 

23 

44 

3.903 

81.963 

1965  Regression 

1.9083 

22 

24 

46 

3.642 

80.124 

1966  Regression 

1.8752 

22 

23 

45 

3.516 

77.352 

1967  Regression 

2.3681 

22 

23 

45 

5.608 

123.376 

1968  Regression 

2.0067 

21 

23 

44 

4.087 

84.567 

1  2 

(Std.  Error  of  Estimate) 


"D.F.    x  MSE 


Fc   = 


(509.2   -  81.963   -  80.124   -   77.352   -   123.376   -  84.567) 

24  ~~  ~~ 


(81.963  +  80.124  +  77.352  +  123.376  +  84.567) 
(224-21-22-22-22-21) 


61.818 


24 =  2.57575 


447.382  3.8567414 

116 


,66786 


Fc  =  .66786  <  F^6  (.01)  -  1.96. 


CHOW  TEST 
INCLUDES  ONLY  FIRMS  WHICH  GENERATE  POWER 


Source  of  Regression 
Statistics 


Pooled  Regression 

1964  Regression 

1965  Regression 

1966  Regression 

1967  Regression 

1968  Regression 


Std.    Error 

S.S. 

of    Estimate 

D.F. 

K 

DF+K 

MSE 

Residuals 

1.3476 

150 

22 

17  2 

1.816 

272.4 

1.6960 

14 

21 

35 

2.876 

40.264 

1.6415 

14 

22 

36 

2.695 

37.73 

1.5872 

13 

21 

34 

2.519 

32.747 

2.0104 

13 

21 

34 

4.042 

52.546 

1.6608 

12 

21 

33 

2.758 

33.096 

(272.4  -  40.264  -  37.73  -  32.747  -  52.546  -  33.096) 

22 
FC  ~  (40.264  +  37.73  t-  32.747  +  52.546  +  33.096) 

(172-14-14-13-13-12) 

76.017 

22  3.45532 


196.383  1.85267 

10  6 


.18650 


Fc  =  1.8650  <  F?n,  (.01)  -  2.00. 


THE  VARIABLES 
The  dependent  variable  is  average  costs  for  the  firm.   Total  cost 
for  the  firm,  excluding  taxes  and  tax  equivalents,  were  divided  by 
annual  sales  in  thousands  of  kilowatt  hours. 


X   Sales  of  Electricity  to  All  Customer  Classifications.   In  millions 
of  kilowatt-hours.   Larger  sales  levels  would  be  expected  to  reduce 
average  costs,  if  economies  of  scale  exists.   (From  Statistics  of 
Publicly  Owned  Electricity  in  the  United  States,  various  years.) 

X   Capacity  Utilization.   Total  generating  capacity  for  each  firm  was 
multiplied  by  8,760  (the  number  of  hours  in  a  365-day  year);  the 
product  is  the  potential  number  of  kilowatt-hours  that  each  firm 
could  have  provided  during  a  year  if  capacity  had  been  fully  utilized, 
without  down  time  for  repairs  or  maintenance.   The  potential  capa- 
city was  divided  into  the  number  of  kilowatts  actually  generated. 
A  higher  rate  of  capacity  utilization  would  be  expected  to  reduce 
average  total  costs.   (Data  from  Statistics  of  Publicly  Owned 
Utilities  in  the  United  States,  various  years.) 


X   Steam  Electric  Fuel  Cost.   Composite  fuel  costs  for  all  firms  within 
a  given  state  were  computed.   These  figures  were  adjusted  for 
burning  efficiency  by  applying  factors  from  Kent  (1950).   The  pro- 
ducts were  then  weighted  by  the  proportionate  utilization  of  steam- 
electric  generation  and  total  generation.   (Fuel  costs  are  from 
Steam  Electric  Plant  Factors,  various  years.) 

X,   Hydroelectric  Fuel  Costs.   This  variable  was  constructed  by  weighting 
the  total  hydroelectric  production  investment  per  kilowatt  of  hydro- 
electric generating  capacity  by  the  proportion  of  total  generation 
accounted  for  by  hydroelectric  generation  (data  from  Statistics  of 
Publicly  Owned  Electric  Utilities  in  the  U.S.). 

'  5  Consumption  per  Commercial  and  Industrial  Customer.   The  actual 
average  annual  consumption  of  commercial  and  industrial  customers 
of  each  utility  (data  from  Statistics  of  Publicly  owned  Electric 
Utilities  in  the  United  States). 

X   Consumption  per  Residential  Customer.   The  actual  average  annual 

consumption  of  power  per  residential  customer.   (Data  from  Statistics 
of  Publicly  Owned  Electric  Utilities  in  the  United  States.) 

X-,   Cost  of  Purchased  Power.   Constructed  by  taking  total  expenditures 


for  purchased  power  divided  by  the  number  of  KWH  purchased.   (Data 
from  Statistics  of  Publicly  Owned  Utilities  in  the  United  States). 


X   Market:  Density  Factor.   This  variable  was  constructed  by  dividing 
the  number  of  thousands  of  square  miles  in  each  city  into  the 
number  of  customers  of  all  classes.   (Customers  from  Statistics  of 

Publicly  Owned  Electric  Utilities  in  the  United  States.   Land  area 

- 

from  U.S.  Department  of  Commerce,  Area  Measurement  Reports,  various 
years.) 

XQ   Internal  Combustion  Generation  Dummy.  This  variable  indicated 

whether  a  firm  produced  any  amount  of  electricity  by  internal 

combustion  generation.   Its  value  was  one  for  firms  that  did,  zero 
otherwise. 

X  -X    Scate  Dummy  Variables.   Indicating  the  state  in  which  the  firm 
was  located. 

X   Competition  Dummy  Variable.   This  variable  was  used  to  indicate 

whether  a  firm  faced  competition;  it  took  a  value  of  one  if  competi- 
tion existed  and  zero  if  not. 


Public  Finance.   There  is  no  variable  in  the  model  to  take  into  account 
the  cost  and  benefits  of  public  finance,  although  it  could  well  be  an 
important  factor,  especially  if  comparisons  were  to  be  made  between 
privately  owned  and  municipally  owned  utility  firms.   The  comparison 
here  is  between  municipally  owned  firms,  not  privately  owned  firms. 
Municipal  governments  do  not  all  have  the  same  tax  rate,  and  some  muni- 
cipally owned  firms  pay  no  taxes  or  tax  equivalent.   The  problem  this 
created  in  cost  comparisons  was  overcome  by  eliminating  all  tax  and 
tax-equivalent  charges  from  the  cost  data.   Municipally  owned  firms  may 
also  enjoy  lower  capital  costs  than  privately  owned  firms  because  of 
lower  external  interest  costs  and  capital  contributions  from  the  muni- 
cipality.  The  first  benefit  was  of  no  consequence  to  the  analysis 
since  only  municipally  owned  firms  were  included.   The  impact  of  the 
second  element  is  difficult  to  assess.   Municipally  owned  utilities 
will  be  disinclined  to  rely  on  capital  contributions  from  the  city  if 
they  seriously  wish  to  tie  costs  to  the  users  of  their  services. 


Furthermore,  there  is  no  reason  to  believe  that  the  benefit  of  such 
capital  contributions  accrued  to  the  competitive  subset  of  firms  more 
than  to  the  other.   It  was  therefore  assumed  that  the  effect,  if  any, 
was  distributed  randomly  among  competitive  and  noncompetitive  firms. 


1ECKMAN 

IINDERY  INC. 

JUN95 

,  "•    „.     f,  N.  MANCHESTER. 
und.-ro-Pleasy   ,ND|ANA  46962