Skip to main content

Full text of "The effect of immigrants on natives' incomes through the use of capital"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANACHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


B24  b   '/-3 


NOTICE;  Return  or  renew  all  Library  Materlalsl  The  Minimum  Fm  for 
each  Lost  Book  Is  $50.00. 

The  person  charging  this  material  is  responsible  for 
Its  return  to  the  library  from  which  it  was  withdrawn 
on  or  before  the  Latest  Date  stamped  below. 
Theft,  mutilation,  and  underlining  of  books  are  reasons  for  discipli- 
nary action  and  may  result  in  dismissal  from  the  University. 
To  renew  call  Telephone  Center,  333-8400 

UNIVERSITY    OF    ILLINOIS    LIBRARY    AT    URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 


DEC  1  0  1935 


L161— O-1096 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/effectofimmigran878simo 


^ 


"^U 


FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  873 


The  Effect  of  Immigrants  on  Natives'  Incomes 
Through  the  Use  of  Capital 

siulian  L  Simon 
A.  James  Heins 


IHE  UBRARV  OF  THE 
S?'.riS?(TypFILUNOIS 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Eccnonic  and  Business  Researcn 
University'  of  Illinois.  Urb&na-Chanpaign 


;l;:i:;li^lilllifii 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  873 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
June  1982 


DepartD 


The  person  charp-inp-  th;. 

sponsible  for  its  rif  ^  material  is  re- 

-^■•ch  it  .as;;  thT;wn°o''''^^fro" 


iicomes 


I  Economics 


Abstract 

This  paper  deals  with  questions  about  the  effects  of  immigrants  on 
three  types  of  capital:   the  private  capital  immigrants  work  with,  the 
public  (government)  capital  that  immigrant  workers  use,  and  the  public 
capital  used  for  services  by  immigrants. 

Private  capital  dilution  is  unimportant.   The  overall  effect  is 
perhaps  1  percent  or  2  percent,  small  enough  to  ignore. 

In  the  government  sector,  workers  can  be  assumed  to  obtain  all  the 
returns  to  capital,  and  about  8  percent  of  immigrants  work  in  this 
sector.   Therefore,  for  productive  capital  taken  altogether,  we  estimate 
that  immigrants  capture  the  returns  from  only  8  percent  of  the  capital 
they  work  with,  the  government  capital;  the  result  is  a  loss  of  perhaps 
2  percent  of  an  immigrant  family's  income  for  one  year,  which  is  about 
the  same  magnitude  as  the  gain  to  natives  through  the  private  capital 
that  immigrants  work  with. 

The  cost  to  natives  of  equipping  an  immigrant  family  with 
"demographic  capital"  —  schools,  hospitals,  and  local  roads  —  turns 
out  to  be  much  more  important.   This  quantity  depends  upon  the  cost  of 
such  equipment,  the  proportion  financed  by  bonds,  the  average  length  of 
life  of  the  capital,  and  the  average  life  of  the  bonds.   We  develop  an 
estimating  equation,  and  calculate  that  the  cost  to  natives  in  1975 
dollars  is  $4172,  about  a  fifth  of  a  year's  income  for  an  average 
family.   This  is  not  insignificant  in  magnitude.   But  this  amount  — 
together  with  the  effect  through  productive  capital  dilution  discussed 
in  the  first  part  of  the  paper  —  is  considerably  smaller  than  the 
benefits  of  immigrants  to  natives  through  their  relatively  low  use  of 
welfare  services  and  their  relatively  high  contribution  of  taxes. 


■1    -I 


*.'. 


:i' ;   1 


j  •..:-■» 


THE  EFFECT  OF  IMMIGRANTS  ON  NATIVES'  INCOMES  THROUGH  THE  USE  OF  CAPITAL 
Julian  L.  Simon  and  A.  James  Heins* 

INTRODUCTION 

Immigrants  are  a  bad  deal  for  natives  because  they  obtain  benefits 
from  capital  they  do  not  pay  for,  according  to  Usher  (1977).   Usher 
reached  this  conclusion  for  the  U.K.  by  applying  the  concept  of  capital- 
returns  capture  developed  by  Borts  and  Stein  (1966) ,  and  by  Berry  and 
Soligo  (1969)  B-S-B-S  hereafter.   The  same  conclusion  would  surely  follow 
for  the  U.S.  and  other  developed  countries  if  one  followed  Usher's  method. 

This  paper  criticizes  Usher's  method  of  applying  the  capital  returns 
concept,  and  proposes  a  new  approach.   This  is  also  a  criticism  of  Simon's 
earlier  inadequate  use  of  the  same  concept  in  the  context  of  Russian 
Jewish  immigrants  into  Israel  (1976).   The  approach  offered  here  leads 
to  a  less  negative  partial  assessment  of  the  effects  of  immigrants  on 
native's  incomes  in  the  U.S.  by  way  of  the  returns  to  capital  than  did  the 
previous  work.** 

A  key  element  in  this  approach  is  separating  the  analysis  of  "pro- 
duction" capital  used  on  the  job  by  immigrants  from  "demographic  consumption" 


*We  appreciate  comments  from  Warren  Sanderson,  Oded  Stark, 
Dan  Usher,  and  a  Hoover  Institution  seminar  group. 

**For  perspective  we  should  note  that  the  effects  through  capital 
use  are  only  a  small  part  of  the  overall  impact  of  immigrants  upon 
natives.   Elsewhere  one  of  us  shows  (Simon,  1981)  that  the  net  balance 
of  transfer  payments  and  taxes  is  positive  and  outweighs  the  negative 
capital-returns  aspect  of  the  immigrant  native's  relationship  to  natives 
that  we  shall  find  here,  leading  to  a  positive  net  effect  of  immigrants' 
effect  on  natives,  even  without  including  the  positive  effect  of  immi- 
grants upon  productivity. 


-2- 

capital  used  in  such  services  as  schooling  and  medical  care.   Within  the 
production  capital  analysis,  a  key  element  is  distinguishing  the  effects 
in  the  private  and  public  sectors.   And  with  respect  to  demographic  capital, 
a  key  element  is  recognizing  that  the  benefits  which  immigrants  obtain  from 
existing  public  capital  are  irrelevant  unless  there  is  a  congestion  effect, 
because  the  existing  capital's  cost  is  sunk  and  largely  has  a  public-goods 
character.  This  approach  allows  us  to  avoid  difficult  issues,  including 
the  interpretation  of  corporate  taxes,  which  are  present  in  Usher's  and 
Simon's  earlier  approach. 

THE  SIZE  OF  THE  CAPITAL-RETURNS-CAPTURE  EFFECT* 
Estimating  satisfactorily  the  amount  of  the  capture  of  returns  to 
capital  by  immigrants  requires  that  we  be  very  careful  about  our  aim. 
We  must  agree  that  the  main  subject  of  inquiry  is  the  creation  of  addi- 
tional output  by  the  immigrant,  and  its  effect  on  natives.   It  is  vital  to 
recognize  that  the  effect  of  this  additional  output  upon  the  immigrant 
himself /herself  is  not  part  of  the  inquiry;  Usher  (1977)  implicitly  did  not 
see  it  that  way,  nor  did  Simon  earlier  (1976),  and  therefore  those  papers 
simply  estimated  the  proportion  of  the  total  capital  in  the  society  from 
which  immigrants  might  receive  returns  either  because  the  capital  is 
owned  privately  or  because  of  corporate  and  other  taxes  in  the  returns 
to  capital.  And  of  course  the  effect  on  the  persons  remaining  in  the 
land  of  emigration  is  not  part  of  the  subject  here. 


^Capture  of  capital  returns"  means  simply  the  receipt  of  payments 
made  to  owners  of  private  productive  capital  through  dividends,  interest 
and  rent. 


-3- 

Let  us  begin  (adopting  Usher's  notation,  diagram  and  general 
approach  for  comparability)  by  noticing  that  the  output  with  an  im- 
migrant (Q  +  AQ) ,  just  as  output  without  the  immigrant  (Q) ,  is  divided 
among  three  types  of  recipients — the  immigrant  employee,  the  owner  of 
the  industrial  capital,  and  the  "government." 

(1)       Q  =  Q  +  Q  =  wL  +  rK  +  Q  (=T) 
P    g     P     P    g 

Q+AO=Q     +AQ     +Q     +AQ     =    (w+Aw) (L  +AL   )    +   (r+Ar) (K  +AK  )   +   (T+AT) 
PPgg  PP  PP 

where     Q  =  native  output 

p  =  the  private  sector 

g  =  the  government  sector 

w  =  the  wage  level  without  immigrants 

L  =  labor  force  without  immigrants 

r  =  after-tax  rate  of  return  to  capital  without  immigrants 

K  =  capital  stock  without  immigrants 

T  =  total  taxes  without  immigrants 

A  =  an  incremental  quantity,  the  difference  between  the 
situation  with  immigrants  compared  to  the  situation 
without  immigrants. 

We  define  private  capital's  "share"  as  what  owners  of  capital  receive 
after  taxes.   It  would  not  seem  sensible  to  discuss  whether  the  taxes 
paid  to  government — corporate  and  "indirect" — come  out  of  "capital's 
full  share"  or  not;  no  definition  of  "capital's  full  share"  would  seem 
to  make  sense  here,  as  consideration  of  these  two  notions  shows:   (1) 
No  economist  would  like  to  argue  that  "capital's  full  share"  is  "capital's 
just  share."   (2)  The  share  of  the  output  that  capital  would  receive  if 


-4- 

govemment  took  no  taxes  is  not  obviously  different  (to  a  first  approxima- 
tion) from  the  share  that  capital  receives  after  taxes,  because  we  can 
assume  that  capital  owners  will  bid  up  to  their  margins  for  the  immigrant's 
services,  and  their  marginal  calculations  will  include  the  tax  effects  of 
hiring  the  immigrant.   So  there  is  little  reason  to  argue  that  the  share 
that  capital  actually  receives  is  different  than  an  ideal  "capital's  share" 
or  "capital's  full  share." 

Focusing  now  on  the  private  sector,  if  capital's  share  is  what  it 
receives,  then  the  only  way  that  an  immigrant  working  in  the  private 
sector  can  receive  some  part  of  the  additional  private  product  (AQ  ) 
other  than  his  own  marginal  product  is  through  corporate  tax  payments. 
Therefore,  we  must  inquire  into  the  nature  of  the  additional  corporate 
taxes  paid  (AT  )  due  to  the  immigrant's  arrival  and  consequent  addi- 
tional outputs. 

The  total  additional  taxes  (AT)  following  on  the  immigrant's  entry 

at  least  balance  the  additional  expenditures  (e.g.,  on  schooling  and 

transfer  payments)  that  occur  because  of  the  immigrant.   (Simon's  recent 

work,  1981,  finds  that  immigrant  families  pay  distinctly  more  in  taxes 

than  they  receive  in  services,  largely  because  of  their  age  composition). 

There  seems  no  reason  not  to  think  of  the  corporate  taxes  that  go  toward 

the  extra  services  for  immigrants  being  in  the  same  proportion  to  total 

taxes  as  they  are  for  all  persons '  services .   That  is ,  AT  >_  AG  and 

AT    T 

— =E.  =  — 2-.   If  so,  there  is  certainly  no  loss  to  natives  by  way  of 

corporate  taxes,  that  is,  AT  is  at  least  as  large  as  the  cost  of  any 

services  to  immigrants  that  it  might  be  expected  to  cover. 


-5- 

Some  of  the  additional  corporate  tax^  payments  may  be  thought  of  as 
rent  on  publicly-owned  capital  used  by  the  corporation,  e.g.,  roads  and 
dams.   And  part  of  this  rent  may  be  gained  by  immigrants,  in  similar  pro- 
portion to  other  citizens.   But  what  matters  here  is  the  effect  on 
natives.   And  the  amount  of  such  "rent"  obtained  by  natives  is  likely 
to  be  of  a  small  order  of  magnitude,  by  any  test,  and  hence  we  shall 
ignore  it  for  convenience  (though  noting  that  excluding  this  factor 
reduces  the  apparent  benefit  of  immigrants  on  natives,  because  we  are 
ignoring  a  flow  that  benefits  natives). 

The  argument  so  far  adds  up  to  the  fact  that  since  AT  >_  AQ  ,  which 
allows  us  to  say  that  AT  =  AQ  and  T  =  Q  ,  we  can  rewrite  (1)  as 

(la)      Q^  =  wL  +  rK 
P     P     P 

Q  +  AQ  =  (w+Aw)(L  +AL  )  +  (r+Ar) (K  +AK  ). 
P     P  P   P  P   P 

If  all  immigrants  worked  in  the  private  sector,  and  we  could  therefore 
treat  the  government  sector  simply  as  if  it  were  a  foreign  company  that 
sells  inputs  to  the  private  sector,  the  B-S-B-S  analysis  would  now  follow 
without  further  ado;  immigrants  would  benefit  natives  as  a  whole  by  the 
celebrated  "triangle"  in  Figure  1. 

But  some  immigrants  work  for  the  government.   In  that  sector  there 
are  no  returns  to  capital  that  natives  capture  but  the  immigrant  in 
question  does  not.   A  key  magnitude  then,  is  the  proportion  of  immigrants 
that  work  for  the  government.   This  must  be  compared  to  the  gain  from 
the  "triangle"  in  order  to  calculate  an  overall  assessment  of  the  impacts 
of  immigrants  through  their  involvement  with  the  capital  used  in  production. 


MARGINAL 
PRODUCT 

OF 
LABOUR 


w+Aw 


I/2ALAW 


(w+Aw)L 


LABOUR 
FORCE 


-6- 

Calculation  of  the  Capture  of  Capital  Returns 

Let  us  begin  by  taking  notice,  as  Usher  demonstrated  by  expanding 
(la)  in  a  Taylor  series,  that  the  "triangle"  of  additional  returns  to 
the  owners  of  private  capital  is  small  when  the  immigration  is  realis- 
tically small;  in  the  context  of  Usher's  Cobb-Douglas  production  func- 
tion example  the  gain  is  about  1/219  of  the  loss  in  labor  income  to 
natives.   And  in  a  simulation  (1976)  Simon  found  that  a  flow  to  immigrants 
of  less  than  a  2%  share  of  the  returns  to  private  capital  is  enough  to 
offset  the  triangle.   Therefore  we  can  ignore  the  B-S-B-S  effect  for 
practical  purposes.   In  short,  then,  the  gain  to  native  capital  and 
the  loss  to  native  labor  almost  wash  each  other  out,  and  immigrants  who 
work  in  the  private  sector  have  little  effect  on  native  per  capita  income. 

But  we  must  still  deal  with  the  public  sector,  and  to  do  that  we 
must  estimate  the  returns  to  public  capital,  by  analogy  with  private 
capital.   Let  us  make  the  simplifying  asstimption  that  the  capital/labor 
ratio  is  the  same  in  government  as  in  industry.  And  for  reasons  of 
data  availability  let  us  estimate  the  ratios  we  need  from  the  non- 
financial  sector  and  project  them  to  the  entire  private  sector.  Let 

W  =  the  amount  paid  for  their  labor  to  employees  in 
wages  and  salaries  in  industry,  $1387  million  in 
1979 

R  =  returns  received  after  corporate  taxes  by  owners  for 
P   the  use  of  their  capital,  $390  million 

Q  =  total  of  employee  compensation  and  after-corporate-tax 

^   returns  to  capital  =  W  +  R  =  $1777 
R  P    P 

■jr^-  =  proportion  of  total  returns  that  go  to  capital  =  22% 

P 
On  standard  classical  assumptions  we  may  identify  the  share  received 

by  labor  as  labor's  marginal  product.  That  is,  the  marginal  immigrant 


-7- 

i 

receives  (100%  -  22%  =)  78%  of  the  total  additional  product  due  to 
him  or  her,  and  the  owners  of  the  capital  receive  22%.   We  could  also 
use  the  stylized  25%-75%  split  used  by  Usher  without  changing  our 
result.   And  to  repeat  a  point  made  earlier,  if  natives  own  the  capital, 
then  the  gain  to  native  capital  owners  balances  out  the  loss  to  native 
workers.  But  if  there  are  no  returns  to  native  capital  owners,  and 
the  immigrant  receives  the  returns  to  both  his/her  labor  and  to  the 
capital  he/she  works  with — as  is  the  case  in  the  public  sector — there 
is  a  loss  to  natives  due  to  the  capital-dilution  effect,  which  makes 
the  marginal  product  of  labor  lower  than  otherwise.   If  we  assume  a 
Cobb-Douglas  production  function  and  the  quantity  of  capital  temporarily 
fixed,  returns  to  native  workers  would  fall  by  an  amount  roughly  equal 
to  the  amount  implied  by  the  22%  gain  to  capital  owners.* 

To  allow  for  the  immigrants  working  in  the  public  sector,  we  must 
obviously  know  the  proportion  working  in  the  public  sector.   From  the 
cohort  of  persons  who  arrived  between  1965  and  1970,  there  were  in  1970 
38,427  males  and  24,256  females,  out  of  454,872  and  309,090  total  persons 
in  the  cohort  employed  of  age  16  or  over,  who  worked  for  the  government — 
that  is,  8.22%,  which  is  much  lower  than  the  16.5%  among  natives  (U.S. 
Bureau  of  the  Census,  United  States  Summary,  Table  93).   For  those  who 
arrived  1960-64,  1955-1959  and  1950-1954,  the  percentages  are  6.8%, 
7.8%,  and  9.0%  respectively.   Say  an  average  of  8%  for  all  immigrants. 
(Immigrants  arriving  more  than  twenty  years  earlier  are  not  very 
relevant  to  a  policy  analysis.) 


♦Distributional  effects  are  not  considered  here.   In  thinking  about 
that  topic,  it  is  important  to  keep  in  mind  that  the  "worker"  class  actually 
obtains  much  of  the  returns  to  capital  through  capital  ox^mership  by  pen- 
sion funds. 


-8- 

If  we  now  assume  that  the  returns  to  the  capital  with  which  the 
government  worker  cooperates  come  to  the  workers,  and  assume  also  the 
same  capital/labor  ratio  and  average  salary  as  in  industry,  then  8% 
of  the  total  returns  to  private  plus  public  capital  due  to  immigrant 
production  flow  to  the  immigrant.   This  is  a  far  cry  from  the  58% 
figure  that  emerged  from  Usher's  method  applied  to  the  U.K. 

A  more  meaningful  comparison  is  the  total  amount  that  natives' 
incomes  fall  relative  to  the  total  wages  of  immigrants  (or  relative 
to  the  total  additional  product  caused  by  the  immigration).   The 
effect  on  native's  incomes  may  be  calculated  as 

Effect  on  natives  =  Income  of  natives  afterwards  minus  income  of 

natives  before  the  immigration  =  total  output 
after  minus  total  output  before  minus  amount 
going  to  immigrants  in  wages  and  capital  capture 

=  (Q+AQ)  -  Q  -  [ALCw+Aw)]  -  4)[K(r+Ar)] 

=  AQ  -  ALCw+Aw)  -  ())[k(r+AR) 

=  ALCw+Aw)  +  AK(r+Ar)  -  AL(w+Aw)  -  (j)[RCr+Ar)] 
where  <J)  is  the  proportion  of  the  returns  to 
capital  captured  by  the  immigrants. 

And  because  AK  =  0  we  can  simplify 

Effect  on  natives  =  <})[K(r+Ar)] 

which  is  the  total  amount  of  the  returns  to  capital  that  is  captured  by 
immigrants.  In  Usher's  calculation  (fi  =  .58,  whereas  in  our  calculation 
9  =  .08*.   The  ratio  of  the  effect  on  natives  to  the  total  wages  of 

immigrants,  then,  is  "P^^)^^^^^  \   With  Usher's  <i>   this  ratio  is  about 


*Usher's  calculation  is  for  the  U.K.,  whereas  ours  is  for  the  U.S., 
but  that  difference  is  a  minor  matter  in  this  context. 


-9- 

.199,  whereas  with  our  <J)  the  ratio  is  about  .028  using  Usher's  75%  share 
to  labor,  or  .025  using  the  above-calculated  78%  share  to  labor. 

The  difference  in  implications  between  Usher's  figure  and  ours  is 
major  no  matter  how  you  look  at  it,  whether  from  an  average  native's 
point  of  view,  an  average  native  worker's  point  of  view,  or  anyone  else's 
pocketbook  point  of  view.  And  a  major  policy  implication  of  this  dif- 
ference appears  in  a  more  global  analysis  of  the  effects  of  immigrants. 
In  the  U.S.  the  balance  of  taxes  and  welfare  expenditures  is  such  that 
natives  gain  considerably  from  the  presence  of  the  average  immigrant 
family,  on  a  present  value  basis.   On  Usher's  calculation,  the  loss  to 
natives  on  the  production-and-income  side  would  more  than  off-balance 
the  tax-and-welfare  gain.  Using  our  calculation  this  is  not  so;  the 
average  family's  net  contribution  to  the  public  coffers  far  outweighs 
the  loss  to  natives  through  immigrant's  capture  of  the  returns  to 
capital, 

CALCULATION  OF  THE  BURDEN 
OF  DEMOGRAPHIC  CAPITAL  WIDENING  DUE  TO  IMMIGRANTS 

Above  we  discussed  the  dilution  of  public  and  private  "production" 

capital  as  it  affects  the  earnings  of  natives.  We  must  now  also  consider 

public  capital  that  immediately  yields  consumption  benefits  to  natives 

and  immigrants,  and  whose  use  is  subject  to  congestion.   This  includes 

such  "demographic  capital"  as  schools  and  hospitals;  more  immigrants 

imply  that  more  of  such  capital  is  needed  if  service  standards  are  not 

to  fall.   On  the  other  hand,  the  Statue  of  Liberty,  intercity  highways, 

and  space  exploration  installations  pretty  clearly  are  public  goods 

whose  use  by  natives  is  unaffected  by  the  number  of  immigrants.   Some 


-10- 

capital,  such  as  new  highway  construction  around  cities,  and  new  physics 
laboratories  at  universities,  is  difficult  to  classify,  but  luckily  most 
public  capital  falls  pretty  clearly  into  one  or  another  of  these  two 
categories. 

A  simple  yet  satisfactory  rule  of  thumb*  is  that  most  chunks  of 
federal  capital  are  true  public  goods,  while  most  chunks  of  local  and 
state  capital  are  demographic  and  subject  to  congestion.   The  state- 
and-local  category  corresponds  fairly  closely  to  the  categories  of  edu- 
cation and  hospitals  and  local  roads.   It  would  probably  be  possible  to 
work  with  the  latter  functional  categories  rather  than  with  the  federal 
versus  state-and-local  distinction,  but  the  results  would  not  likely  be 
substantially  different. 

It  may  help  to  begin  with  this  question:   Why  does  any  community 
allow  additional  native  American  persons  to  move  into  the  tax  district 
without  assessing  penalties  to  pay  for  the  public  capital  the  person 
will  use?  A  church  or  synagogue  or  mosque  that  builds  a  new  building 
free  and  clear  from  savings  or  current  assessments  is  likely,  for  a 
number  of  years  after  the  new  building  is  built,  to  assess  a  new  member 
a  special  building  fee  over  and  above  the  dues  that  old  and  new  members 
pay.   Why  does  not  a  city  or  state  do  the  same  (assuming  away  legal 
impediments)?   The  answer  would  seem  to  be  that  new  members  of  a 
community  pay  on  average  "rent"  for  the  capital  they  use,  at  least 
enough  to  cover  a  considerable  part  of  the  additional  cost  of 
any  necessary  capital  widening  on  this  account.   This  is  because — in 


*Fred  Giertz  suggested  this. 


-11- 

contradistinction  to  a  religious  congregation  that  finances  a  new 
building  without  borrowing — a  large  part  of  public  capital  is  built  with 
borrowed  money.  And  with  their  taxes,  new  dwellers  help  pay  the  service 
of  this  debt  to  an  extent  that  the  new  dweller  is  not  a  burden  on  old 
dwellers  in  this  respect. 

If  all  demographic  construction — such  as  schools  and  hospitals  and  other 
local  facilities  whose  size  must  be  affected  by  numbers  of  people  (called 
just  "construction"  or  "structure"  hereafter) — were  financed  by  consol 
bonds,  the  immigrants  would  be  paying  more  taxes  than  if  they  used  only 
structures  built  for  them  and  if  they  also  paid  entirely  for  that  con- 
struction which  they  used.   (Underlying  the  latter  part  of  this  sentence 
is  a  model  of  constant  iiranigration  under  simple  conditions.  For  now  this 
is  only  to  be  a  vague  statement  of  self-financing  as  the  benchmark.)   This 
is  simply  because  immigrants  and  their  descendants  would  then  be  paying 
a  full  share  for  all  new  construction,  and  would  be  paying  also  for  some 
structures  that  had  obsolesced  and  were  no  longer  in  use;  by  the  same 
token,  they  would  be  paying  more  than  their  share  for  partly-obsolesced 
structures . 

On  the  other  hand,  if  all  construction  were  paid  for  on  a  current 
basis,  immigrants  would  underpay  for  the  structures  they  use,  because  they 
would  pay  only  a  part  (on  a  per  head  basis  equal  to  natives)  for  the  new 
construction  necessary  for  them,  whereas  all  of  the  cost  of  the  new 
construction  would  be  due  only  to  them  (causing  increased  expenditure 
by  natives  for  the  new  construction)  while  not  paying  at  all  for  existing 
structures  they  would  be  using.   And  if  the  number  of  immigrants  were  small 
and  there  were  little  or  no  physical  depreciation,  natives  would  pay  almost 


-12- 

the  entire  cost  of  structures  for  immigrants.   This  point  comes  out 
clearly  if  we  notice  that  if  all  construction  depreciated  in  say  a  year 
(the  tax  period),  natives  would  not  be  footing  any  of  the  bill  for  immi- 
grants; all  would  then  be  on  an  equal  footing.   But  since  depreciation 
takes  longer  than  the  current  period,  and  since  natives  have  already  built 
and  paid  for  much  of  the  construction  they  need,  the  additional  construc- 
tion for  natives  would  be  more  than  they  would  otherwise  need  (by  a  pro- 
portion greater  than  the  proportion  of  new  immigrants  to  natives).   This 
last  statement  has  not  been  stated  rigorously,  but  should  be  made  con- 
vincing by  this  third  possibility:  With  respect  to  construction  financed 
by  debt,  if  the  length  of  life  of  construction  equals  the  length  of  time 
during  which  the  debt  is  serviced,  asssuming  equal  payments  on  the  debt 
each  year  (that  is,  assuming  that  the  building  collapses  the  day  it  is 
paid  off),  and  if  the  cost  of  construction  and  quality  of  buildings  re- 
main constant,  then  an  immigrant  would  exactly  pay  for  the  cost  of  new 
construction  built  on  his  or  her  account.   He/she  would  a)  pay  a  full 
share  for  new  buildings  built  this  year,  like  any  native;  b)  pay  nothing 
for  buildings  no  longer  in  use;  and  c)  pay  proportional  to  the  remaining 
length  of  life  for  older  buildings  still  in  service. 

Therefore,  we  wish  to  combine  the  necessary  elements — length  of 
capital  life,  length  of  bond  period,  proportion  of  capital  financed  by 
borrowing,  together  with  the  cost  of  equipping  an  average  immigrant 
family — into  an  estimating  equation,  develop  estimates  of  the  elements, 
and  calculate  the  burden  on  immigrants  per  immigrant  family.   We  begin 
with  notation: 


-13- 


Cost  of  contruction  per  unit 
of  capital  necessary  for 

an  additional  family  =  C 

Proportion  of  construction  cost 

financed  by  bonds  =  c 

Length  of  life  of  a  unit  -I 

Bond  period  =  b 

Total  native  population  of  families  =  P  =  P 

t    t-1 

Units  in  existence         •   .  =  Q»  and  Q/P  =  1 

Units  built  =  q 

Number  of  immigrant  families  =  1=1 

Expenditures  =  E 

Taxes,  total  paid  =  T 

Without  immigrant  superscript  =  o 

With  immigrant  superscript  =  I 


Q  =  P 
t    t 

q°  =  -4  Q^_n   in  steady  state,  the  number  of  units  necessary 
to  replace  units  worn  out  after  H   years, 

1)  ^t  ~  T  '^t-l  ^       expenditures  each  year  in  steady  state 

without  the  immigrants 

2)  ^t  ~  T  ^t-1  ^  ■*■  ^  expenditures  with  the  immigrants,  because 

one  additional  unit  is  needed  for  I 

^^    ^t°  =  i  ^^t-b  ^  i  -^Cb+i  '"^''h^  ^^-^K  =  ^t  ^^  '^^^^y 

state,  that  is,  total  taxes  yearly  without  immigrants,  which  includes 


-14- 


debt  payments  on  capital  financed  in  the  past  plus  current  payments 
on  the  portion  of  current  expenditures  not  financed  by  debt* 

T°   -  Q°   C 

—  =  r =  yC  because  Q  =  P^  =  P.  ,  ,  taxes  per  person 

^t      ^t      ^  t    t-1 

without  "immigrant  in  steady  state 

4)  T  =  E  +  —  cC  +  (l-c)C  because  the  firsfr  payment  on  the 
financial  portion  of  additional  unit  will  be  made  in  t,  plus  the  non- 
financial  portion's  payment 

5)  T^  -  T^  =  T-  cC  +  (l-c)C  increase  in  total  taxes  in  t  due 

t    to 

to  immigrant 

1  T^    c      1 

6)  -g  cC  +  Cl-c)C  -  pVT   Cr  +  1-c  -  y)C  is  the  increase  in  burden  of 
taxes  to  natives  in  first  year  because  of  an  immigrant.   The  total 

burden  over  the  years  to  natives  is 

7)  b(—  -  y)cC  +  (l-c)C  because  of  the  payment  on  the  finance 
portion  of  the  increment  until  the  additional  unit  is  paid  for.   Aside  from 
that,  immigrant  henceforth  simply  constitutes  a  proportional  increase  in  the 
society  and  has  no  effect  on  natives. 


*We  shall  assume  that  the  bonds  are  amortized  at  a  constant  rate 
over  their  lives,  that  is,  equal  payments  in  each  period  until  retire- 
ment, in  the  manner  of  a  house  mortgage.   In  reality,  a  given  bond  issue 
is  floated  with  bonds  of  a  variety  of  maturities,  and  the  tax  burden 
declines  as  more  bonds  are  retired.   But  the  constant-amortization 
assumption  must  be  a  satisfactory  approximation  for  our  purposes  here. 


-15- 

8)  The  overall  magnitude  of  the  loss  to  natives  (if  there  is  one) 
depends,  of  course,  upon  the  proportion  of  capital  investment  that  is 
funded  with  debt,  and  upon  the  cost  of  the  units,  but  also  heavily  upon 
£,  the  length  of  life  of  the  structure.   If  I   is  very  short,  the 
immigrants  pay  for  structures  already  destroyed,  even  if  the  bond  period 
is  also  short.   If  the  length  of  life  is  very  long,  then  the  cost  to 
natives  approaches  the  full  cost  of  the  structure.  Therefore,  to  estimate 
the  effect,  we  need  to  know  C,  b,  H.      I/P  may  be  assiamed  to  be  very 
small. 

9)  We  may  estimate  C  in  several  rough  ways  which,  if  they  generally 
agree,  should  allow  us  to  have  some  confidence  in  the  composite  estimate. 
(1)  The  current  replacement  value  of  government  capital  (structures, 
inventory  and  equipment)  at  the  end  of  1975  was  estimated  by  Kendrick 
(1976)  to  be  $981  billion.  Dividing  that  total  among  units  of  govern- 
ment on  the  basis  of  capital  outlay  figures  by  the  various  units  of 
government  plus  tentative  depreciation  yields  an  estimated  $781.5  bil- 
lion as  the  value  of  state  and  local  capital  at  the  end  of  1975.   Its 
ratio  to  GNP  in  the  corresponding  year  was  38.1  percent.  Therefore, 

one  may  assume  that  it  costs  an  amount  equal  to  that  proportion  times 
the  representative  family's  income  to  equip  an  additional  representative 
family. 

A  rough  check  for  this  magnitude  uses  the  observation  that  employment 
in  the  state-and-local  sector  is  14.1  percent  of  all  employment.   If  the 
capital-output  ratio  is  2  in  that  sector  as  in  the  rest  of  the  economy, 
and  if  average  income  is  the  same  in  that  sector  as  is  the  rest  of  the 
economy,  then  a  sum  equal  to  2  x  14.1%  =  28.2%  average  income  is  the  value 


-16- 

of  such  capital  for  the  average  family.   The  value  in  1979  for  the  median 
primary  family  (Statistical  Abstract  of  the  U.S.,  1980,  p.  451;  the  mean 
value  for  all  families  would  be  better,  but  will  not  be  sufficiently  dif- 
ferent to  make  a  difference  here)  was  (.381  x  $19,684  =)  $7500. 

10)  The  average  bond  period  b  is  10.53  years,  estimated  as  described 
in  the  appendix. 

11)  The  average  length  of  life  of  state-and-local  capital  is 
14.76  years,  estimated  as  described  in  the  appendix. 

12)  The  value  of  c,  the  proportion  of  the  capital  that  is  financed 
with  debt,  is  approximated  .62,  as  described  in  the  appendix. 

13)  Calculating  now  by  inserting  the  necessary  values  into  (7)  the 
average  cost  to  natives  of  equipping  an  immigrant  family,  assuming  the 
family's  income  and  use  of  services  is  average,  is  then  $4172  or  21% 

of  a  year's  income  for  a  family,  without  discounting  the  future  pajrments. 

Without  further  ado  or  the  relatively  minor  adjustments  called  for 
by  a  variety  of  factors  working  in  both  directions,  let  us  hit  upon  one 
fifth  of  the  average  family's  inocme  as  the  cost  of  equipping  the 
community  for  an  additional  average  family's  needs.   For  this  to  be  an 
appropriate  cost  for  an  average  immigrant  family  requires  that  it  be  of 
the  same  size  and  composition  as  an  average  native  family.   This  is 
probably  not  so  far  from  the  fact  as  to  make  inappropriate  21%  of  family 
income  as  the  estimate. 

This  cost  is  certainly  not  negligible  even  when  the  returns  to  gov- 
ernment capital  from  government  immigrant  workers  are  added.   However, 
it  is  considerably  smaller  than  the  present  value  of  the  net  of  taxes 


-17- 

paid  and  transfers  received  by  immigrants — which  are  perhaps  1.5  or  2 
times  the  average  native  family  income  (Simon,  1981) — and  hence  the 
capital  effect  does  not  dominate  the  overall  impact  of  immigrants  upon 
natives'  standard  of  living,  which  is  positive  on  balance  even  without 
considering  the  effect  on  natives  through  increased  productivity,  and 
the  latter  almost  surely  swamps  all  other  effects  in  the  long  run  (Simon, 
1982). 

SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSIONS 

There  are  three  questions  about  capital  and  immigrants  we  must 
answer:   The  effect  through  private  capital  which  immigrants  work  with, 
the  effect  through  public  capital  that  immigrant  workers  use,  and  the 
effect  through  public  capital  used  for  services  by  immigrants. 

The  first  question,  the  issue  of  private  capital  dilution,  can  be 
dealt  with  swiftly.  Sorts  and  Stein,  and  Berry  and  Soligo,  showed  that 
while  workers  as  workers  lose  through  lower  wages  due  to  immigrant 
workers,  owners  of  capital  benefit  by  something  more  than  the  workers 
lose,  and  hence  per-person  income  goes  up  in  the  society.   The  overall 
effect  is  small  by  Usher's  and  Simon's  reckonings,  perhaps  1%  or  2%, 
small  enough  to  forget. 

If  all  immigrants  worked  in  private  industry,  and  if  there  were  no 
corporate  income  taxes,  we  could  now  also  forget  about  the  entire  sub- 
ject of  production  capital  dilution.   Usher  tackled  the  second  and  third 
of  these  problems  together  by  analyzing  the  properties  of  public  and 
private  capital  for  the  U.K.   Simon  did  much  the  same  for  Israel,  inde- 
pendently.  Usher  arrived  at  the  conclusion  that  58%  of  the  returns  to 
all  the  capital  they  work  with  are  captured  by  immigrants  even  if  they 


-18- 

own  no  private  capital,  and  therefore  immigrants  are  a  major  burden 
upon  natives.   And  of  course  in  Usher's  model  there  is  no  positive 
effect  of  immigrants  upon  productivity  to  counterbalance  the  effect 
Usher  calculated.   For  the  productive  capital,  we  estimate  that  immi- 
grants capture  the  returns  from  only  8%  of  the  capital  they  work,  with, 
which  is  the  government  capital  only;  the  result  is  a  loss  of  perhaps 
2%  of  an  immigrant  family's  income  for  one  year,  which  is  about  the  same 
size  as  the  gain  to  natives  through  the  private  capital  that  immigrants 
work.  with. 

The  cost  to  natives  of  equipping  the  immigrant  family  with  "demo- 
graphic capital" — schools,  hospitals,  and  local  roads — depends  upon  the 
cost  of  such  equipment,  the  proportion  financed  by  bonds,  the  average 
length  of  life  of  the  capital,  and  the  average  bond  life.   We  develop 
an  estimating  equation,  and  calculate  that  the  cost  to  natives  in  1975 
dollars  is  $4172,  about  a  fifth  of  a  year's  income  of  an  average  family. 
This  is  not  insignificant  in  magnitude,  but  this  amount — together  with 
the  effect  through  productive  capital  dilution  discussed  in  the  first 
part  of  the  paper — is  considerably  smaller  than  the  benefits  of  immi- 
grants to  natives  through  their  relatively  low  use  of  welfare  services 
and  their  relatively  high  contribution  of  taxes. 


-19- 


References 


R.  Albert  Berry  and  Ronald  Soligo,  "Some  Welfare  Aspects  of  International 
Migration,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy.  77:778-94,  Sept. /Oct.  1969. 

George  H.  Borts  and  Jerome  L.  Stein,  Economic  Growth  in  a  Free  Market 

(New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1966).   Quoted  by  Usher,  1977. 

John  W.  Kendrick,  et.  al..  The  National  Wealth  of  the  United  States 
(New  York:  The  Conference  Board,  March  1976). 

Julian  L.  Simon,  "The  Economic  Effect  of  Russian  Immigrants  Upon  the 

Veteran  Israeli  Population:  A  Cost-Benefit  Analysis,"  The  Economic 
Quarterly,  23,  August  1976,  pp.  244-253,  (in  Hebrew). 

Julian  L.  Simon,  "The  Really  Important  Effects  of  Immigrants  Upon  Natives' 
Incomes,"  in  Barry  Chiswick  (ed.).  Conference  on  Immigration, 
(Washington:  American  Enterprise  Institute,  forthcoming). 

Julian  L.  Simon,  "What  Do  Immigrants  Take  From,  and  Give  to,  the  Public 
Coffers?"  done  for  the  Selection  Commission  on  Immigration  and 
Refugee  Policy,  August,  1980,  to  be  published  in  Spring,  1981. 

Dan  Usher,  "Public  Property  and  the  Effects  of  Migration  Upon  Other 

Residents  of  the  Migrants'  Countries  of  Origin  and  Destination," 
Journal  of  Political  Economy,  Volume  85,  1977,  pp.  1001-1026. 


M/D/329 


APPENDIX 


Estimating  the  Length  of  Life  of  Capital 
1')       K  =  Cq  +  (l-d)C  +  (l-d)^C2  +  ...  Adam  and  Eve 


where ! 


K  =  current  value  of  total  demographic  capital 
c.  =  construction  cost  of  demographic  capital  i  periods  ago 
d  =  rate  of  depreciation. 
Now,  let: 

2')       C.  =C.^^(l+g) 

where : 

3')       g  =  d  +  p  +  r  +  s 

Here  we  argue  that  the  rate  of  growth  of  construction  is  equal  to  the 
rate  of  depreciation  plus  the  population  growth  rate  (p)  plus  the  rate 
of  inflation  (r)  plus  the  rate  of  increase  of  the  standard  of  unit  pro- 
vision (s). 

Inserting  2'  and  3'  into  1'  and  solving  the  infinite  series  yields: 

n     1  A 

4')       K  =  lim  E  [.^  ill.  ^AC. 

_  "•  1+r+p+s+d  ■"  1 
n^«  0      '^ 


^        ,l+2(rj2+s)+3d, 
0  ^   r+p+s+d   J 


Solving; 


l+(2  -  ^)(p+r+s) 
5')       d^ ^ 

^-  3 


-A2- 


Finally: 

6')       ^4 

Here  we  estimate  the  values  of  i   and  d  by  using  national  wealth 
estimates  from  Kendrick,  et.  al.  (1976),  population  growth  data  from 
the  Bureau  of  the  Census,  and  price  data  from  the  Bureau  of  Labor 
Statistics,,  and  income  data  from  the  Department  of  Commerce.   Kendrick 
estimates  that  the  value  of  government  wealth  in  structures,  inventories, 
and  equipment  was  $815  billion  in  1973,  valued  in  current  dollars. 
Gross  investment  in  1973  was  estimated  to  be  $85.5  billion.*  Since 
Kendrick  does  not  provide  separate  estimates  of  state  and  local  wealth, 
we  assume  the  average  depreciation  rate  to  be  the  same  in  all  government 
sectors. 

From  1960-73,  the  U.S.  population  grew  (p)  at  an  estimated  annual 
rate  of  1.19  percent.   The  average  price  of  government  purchases  (r) 
increased  at  a  rate  of  4.73  percent.  We  use  as  a  proxy  for  the  increase 
in  the  standard  of  public  good  provision  (s)  the  increase  in  real  per- 
capita  gross  national  product  from  1960  to  1973,  estimated  to  be  1.49 
percent. 

Inserting  these  estimates  into  formulae  5'  and  6'  yields 
d  =  6.78  percent 
a  =   14.76  years. 


*These  estimates  were  derived  by  continuing  the  relationship  re- 
vealed in  Tables  2-1  and  3-A  in  Kendrick  (1976). 


-A3- 

Estimating  the  Bond  Period 
Let: 


1")       D  =  I  -  R  +  I  -  R  +  . . .  Adam  and  Eve 


where : 

D.  =  current  value  of  debt  end  of  period  i 

I.  =  gross  borrowing  i  periods  ago 

R.  =  debt  retirement  i  periods  ago. 

This  says  that  the  current  value  of  the  debt  is  equal  to  the  sum  of  all 
past  borrowing  minus  debt  retirements.   It  follows  that: 

2")       I.  =  D.  -  D.  ,  +  R. 
11    1-1    1 

This  says  that  gross  borrowing  in  period  i  equals  the  value  of  ending 
debt  minus  beginning  debt  plus  bond  retirement  during  period  i. 

If  we  assume  a  maturity  period  equal  to  b — the  value  to  be  esti- 
mated— we  get : 

3")       R.  =  I.  +  b 
1    1 

recalling  that  b  =  bond  period. 

That  is,  debt  retirement  in  period  i  equals  gross  borrowing  b  periods 

previous.   Then,  it  follows  that: 


4")       D-  =  lim  E  I.  -  lim  Z  I. 
n-*<»  0      n^«>  b 


=  lim  [Z   I.  -  E  I.] 

n-^  0  ^   b  ^ 

To  facilitate  the  solution  we  assume; 


-A4- 


5")       I.  =  I._j_^(l+g),  where 


g  =  the  rate  of  growth  of  borrowing 


Then: 


^0  y^ 


and,  finally: 
7")       b  = 


ln(-^)  -  InClQ  + -^  -  Dq) 
ln(l+g) 


Using  the  above  formulae  we  estimate  the  average  maturity  of 
debt  (b)  based  on  data  for  the  period  1960-73.   Census  of  government 
data  show  state  and  local  net  debt  of  $158.7  billion  in  1973,  new  issues 
of  $21.8  billion  in  fiscal  1973,  and  a  grand  rate  of  8.07  percent  in 
new  issues  over  the  is  period.   Plugging  these  figures  into  formula  7" 
yields : 

b  =  10.53  years.  '    ^ 

Financing  Capital  Outlay 
Next  we  estimate  the  percentage  of  capital  outlay  that  is  financed 
by  bond  issuance.  We  assume  that  all  debt  retirement  is  tax  financed 
as  part  of  the  normal  amortization  process.   It  follows  that  proceeds 
of  all  long-term  debt  issues  are  used  to  finance  capital  outlay.  We 
use  figures  from  1973  for  purposes  of  comparability  with  data  we  used 
to  estimate  other  parameters  in  our  argument.*  Thus: 


*Data  are  taken  from  U.S.  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Compendium  of 
Government  Finances,  1972-73. 


-A5- 


p  _  new  bonds  issued  _  $21.8  billion  _ 
capital  outlay     $35.3  billion  ~ 


:■*:!:  ■-. 


;';''^'li  t:!'4!.  \i'\ 


CKMAN       m 
)ERY  INC.        |M1 

JUNSS 

o-Pkuf  N.  MANCHESTER.