Skip to main content

Full text of "The effects of complex capital structure on the market values of firms"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  Of 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

ikL  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

STACKS 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/effectsofcomplex579frec 


Faculty  Working  Papers 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administrati 

Unlv.ril»yoflMlnoi$atUrbana-Champalgn 


FACULTY  iraRKBTG  PAPERS 
College  of  Conmerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaiga 
June  11,  1979 


TIIE  EFFECTS  OF  COIIPLEX  CAPITAL  STP^UCTURE 
Oil  TIIE  l-IATJCET  VALUES  OF  FIPJIS 

Thrmas  J.  Frecka,  Assistant  Professor, 
Department  of  Accountancy 

//579 


Summary: 

'■  In  this  study,  the  familiar  llodigliani  and  lliller  risk  class  model  provided  the  ba; 
to  test  for  a  difference  in  value  between  simple  and  complex  capital  structure  groups  oJ 
firms  in  the  same  risk  class.  Cluster  analysis,  using  market  risk  measures  and  debt-eq» 
ratios  as  inputs,  provided  the  method  for  obtaining  the  required  risk  class  sample  of 
firms.  Cross  sectional  tests  at  the  end  of  1972,  1973,  and  1974,  for  the  sample  of  26 
complex  capital  structure  firms,  indicated  that  capital  structure  v/as  a  highly  signific; 
effect.  For  all  periods  examined,  the  complex  capital  structure  firms  were  valued  lovjei 
than  the  simple  capital  structure  firms.  One  explanation  for  the  results  is  that  most  ( 
tl^e  convertible  securities  for  the  complex  capital  structure  group  were  overhanging  issi 
during  the  test  period. 

Ackno\/ledy;ment : 

•t 

The  author  gratefully  acknowleges  the  help  of  George  H.  Frankfurter,  xrho  helped 
formulate  the  research  question,  and  chaired  the  dissertation  on  \;hich  this  study  is  ba; 


The  Effects  of  Complex  Capital  Structure 
on  the  Market  Values  of  Firms 


Thomas  J.  Frecka* 

I.  Introduction 

Spurred  by  the  seminal  work  of  Modlgliani  and  Miller  [19],  an  issue 
of  continuing  concern  and  controversy  in  the  field  of  finance  has  been 
the  effect  of  the  financing  decision  on  firm  market  values.  Despite  the 
persistance  of  controversy,  progress  has  been  made  at  both  theoretical 
and  empirical  levels.  At  the  theoretical  level,  the  MM  arbitrage  proofs 
have  been  extended  and  illustrated  to  hold  in  a  variety  of  contexts 


1  '  ' 

by  numerous  authors.   And  those  theorists  who  continue  to  believe  that 

capital  structure  matters  have  turned  from  ad  hoc  rationalization  to 
more  explicit  consideration  of  the  effects  of  certain  market  imperfec- 
tions. At  the  empirical  level,  the  main  progress  stems  from  the  use  of 

increasingly  sophisticated  econometric  techniques  to  deal  with  a  variety 

2 
of  measurement  problems.   As  a  minimum,  the  result  of  continuing 

research  during  the  last  twenty  years  has  been  to  raise  the  discussion 

to  a  higher  plane. 

Despite  the  plethora  of  research  dealing  with  capital  structure  and 

value  relationships,  neither  the  theory  nor  empirical  tests  of  the  MM 

risk  class  model  have  explicitly  considered  the  Impact  of  convertible. 

securities  and  warrants  on  firm  market  values.   This  is  somewhat  surpris- 

4 
ing  given  the  continuing  interest  in  these  forms  of  financing  and  the 

sometimes  confusing  reasons  given  for  their  issuance,  as  explained  below. 


*llniversity  of  Illinois,  Champaign-Urbana.  This  paper  is  a  summary 
of  my  dissertation,  completed  at  Syracuse  University  in  1978.   Grateful 
acknowledgement  is  given  to  George  M.  Frankfurter,  who  served  as  chair- 
man, and  helped  formulate  the  research  question. 


-2- 

A  major  purpose  of  this  study  Is  to  investigate  empirically  the 
effects  of  complex  capital  structure  on  firm  market  values.  This  is 
accomplished  by  testing  for  a  difference  in  value  between  simple  and 
complex  capital  structure  groups  of  firms  in  the  same  risk  class. 

Despite  the  variety  of  analytic  proofs  showing  that  the  existance 
of  security  types  simply  results  in  a  fragmentation  of  the  firm's  total 
earnings  stream  among  various  security  holders,  suggestions  that  coiq>lez 
capital  structure  may  impact  on  firm  values  are  prevalent.  These  sug- 
gestions are  evaluated  in  Part  II.  Related  to  this  point,  arbitrage 
proofs  for  the  complex  capital  structure  case  within  the  two  period 
risk  class  model  are  shown  in  Appendix  1. 

An  important  assumption  of  the  MM  theory  is  that  firms  can  be 

assigned  to  equivalent  risk  classes.  Part  III  discusses  limitations  of 

previous  risk  class  approaches  and  suggests  the  use  of  a  new  procedure 

based  on  cluster  analysis, 

*  ,- 
Part  IV  discusses  sanpie  selection  procedures,  measurement  pro- 

■••■■-■■-■■  ■"  ■-:  y'lr.'    ...  ..  jr=.:  .::<.v 

cedures,  statistical  tests,  and  results. 

r  ->   ;■   -■   j~»  » 

A  summary  is  provided  in  Part  V,  including  limitations  and  sug- 

gestions  for  future  research. 

■   ■•■'•■   "•'  ■  ■■   '  ':■■'' ^. '' ■'.'"■-'      ..-'  '■[':■'."-.■    ■._..;  'XB''::'  -^"iJ/iL;_'£  "jf. .■!,:,'./ 

II.  Reasons  Coiaplex  Capitrl  Structure  May  Inpact  on  Firm  Values 

The  traditional  view  concerning  the  effect  of  convertible  securities 

■'  ■■■■  •  ■'  :  ■•  ■:■-■:   ■■'   ■■■"■    :  ■  ■  -  ,:,  ,:_,_2   ■^•i^fk-^,  ^:^ 

on  value  is  expressed  by  Johnson  [15,  p.  403]  as  follows. 

But  the  dilution  of  earnings  per  share  is  not  neces- 
sarily equivalent  to  the  dilution  of  price  per  share. 
Although  conversion  brings  a  drop  of  earnings  per   '    T" 
share  ...»  it  does  not  follow  that  the  market  value 

■  •■  •■  ■.....;.  ..  .^;..s!...-  ,.  ,.  ..-,.  ...  X  i  ;'V'E'v",i;.l.  \:t  ''ji 
■'"•""''•  •■'{..:'■  '  v  -v..  ■  .•  ;/  ;.  'L,^  ji  ■:t:a:::..':  '■ 
•     -^    -■  ^^ '■•...••;■;  a    -i   &,■(.:.,■:■  •• 


-3- 


of  comQDn  stock  will  decline  by  the  same  percentage. 
Given  the  smaller  financial  risk  attributable  to  the 
common  stock  because  of  the  reduction  of  financial 
leverage,  the  price-earnings  ratio  may  rise  to  off- 
set in  part  the  decline  in  earnings. 

The   above  statement  suggests  that  current  shareholders  react  to  a  com- 
bined dilution  and  leverage  effect  associated  with  convertible  securities. 
But  the  main  concern  is  with  dilution. 

Dilution  represents  an  expropriation  of  value  without  appropriate 
compensation.   In  a  perfect  market,  it  is  assumed  that  security  holders 
protect  themselves  from  dilution  by  a  variety  of  "me  first"  rules.  With 
respect  to  convertible  securities,  while  the  firm  and  current  shareholders 
do  suffer  an  opportunity  loss  upon  conversion,  this  loss  is  not  without  . 
compensation.  For  in  a  perfect  market,  this  opportunity  loss  should  be 
exactly  offset  by  the  present  value  of  accumulated  savings  in  interest 
due  to  originally  issuing  the  convertible  security  instead  of  straight 
debt.   But  even  if  dilution  in  the  above  sense  is  possible,  this  only 

means  that  classes  of  security  holders  may  not  be  indifferent  to  capital 

8 
structure.  Total  firm  value  should  be  unaffected. 

Another  set  of  arguments  Is  based  on  the  belief  that  management  can 
more  accurately  estimate  the  firm's  growth  opportunities  than  the  market. 
These  arguments  are  based  on  the  empirical  fact  that,  on  average,  com- 
panies experience  much  higher  stock  price  appreciation  before  issuing 
complex  securities  than  occurs  after  the  securities  are  issued. 

It  has  been  shown  that  investors  are  willing  to  pay  a  premium  for 

9 
past  growth  indicating  their  optimism  that  It  will  continue.   The 

in5)licatlon  is  that  managers  believe  they  can  successfully  "fool  the ' 

market"  regarding  growth,  thus  resulting  in  overvalued  complex  securities 

and  firms. 


-4- 

A  sooewhat  contrary  explanation  of  how  management  might  act  If  it 
perceived  the  market  was  unable  to  impound  growth  opportunities  is  as 
follows.  If  management  believed  its  firm's  common  stock  to  be  under- 
priced,  perhaps  due  to  nondisclosure  of  a  recently  developed  growth 
opportunity  or  the  market's  failure  to  impound  a  disclosed  growth  oppor- 
tunity in  current  stock  prices,  convertible  securities  could  be  issued 
to  finance  such  opportunities.  When  the  investment  resulted  in  Increased 
iearnings,  conversion  would  occur.  The  implication  is  that  management 
seeks  to  ptotect  current  shareholders  from  the  effects  (if  any)  of 
current  earnings  dilution  by  issiiing  the  convertible  security  rather 
than  currently  issuing  stock.  -xv-'  ■  c»'> 

Although  the  difficulty  of  defining,  measuring,  and  forecasting 
growth  is  admitted,  it  seems  unlikely  that  the  market  is  unable  to  make 
unbiased  estimates  of  growth  based  on  the  information  set  available.   ;. 
The  substantial  empirical  evidence  concerning  market  efficiency  in  a 
variety  of  contexts  might  lead  us  to  suspect  that  the  market  is  also 
efficient  regarding  growth.  But  empirical  tests  will,  hopefully,  con- 
firm or  deny  this  suspicion.  ... 

A  final  suggestion  as  to  why  complex  capital  structure  might  affect 
market  value  Is  based  on  the  leverage  preferences  of  "gamblers."  Al-  „ 
though  equity  and  debt  markets  are  dominated  by  risk  averse  investors, 
this  is,  less  likely  to  be  true  in  markets  for  convertible  securities, 
warrants,  and  options.  Given  the  well-known  leverage  opportunities 
associated  with  these  latter  securities,  risk  loving  investors  may  bid 
up  the  price  of  these  securities  and  firms  in  periods  of  high  growth. 
Presumably  the  opposite  effect  would  occur  if  anticipated  growth  was 
not  forthcoming,  e.g.,  the  overhanging  issue  case.  .,.  -._^^ 


-5- 

Despite  the  above  arguments  to  the  contrary,  the  crux  of  capital 
structure  theory,  given  perfect  market  assumptions,  stresses  the  inde- 
pendence of  total  firm  value  and  capital  structure.  Fama  and  l-Iiller 
[9]  analyze  the  issue  first  in  a  general  equilibrium  setting  and  then 
present  the  well-known  arbitrage  arguments  using  partial  equilibrium  ^r.  ■ 
states  of  the  world  and  risk  class  approaches.  Hamada  [12,  13]  has  pro-^ 
vided  the  analytic  link  between  the  risk  class  model  and  the  capital  ,.  • 
asset  pricing  model.  Finally,  Merton  [17]  has  provided  the  analytic 
link  between  the  Black  and  Scholes  [3]  option  pricing  model  and  the  risk 
class  model.  ■     ■  .  .  u:^:  =  ^;^m  ,:iT^..:: 

Iheory  suggests  that  the  separation  principle  should  continue  to 
hold  for  the  complex  capital  structure  case.  While  a  strict  indepen- 
dehce  will  not  hold  given  imperfections  such  as  taxes   and  assuming  ... 
risky  debt,  these  considerations  are  no  more  or  less  present  for  simple 
or  complex  capital  structiires  and  should  not  affect  test  results.  , 
Arbitrage  proofs  using  a  two  period  risk  class  model  are  Illustrated  for 
the  complex  capital  structure  case  in  Appendix  1.       .  ■■  i     ;.■■--::;::.• 

III.  The  Risk  Class  Assumption 
I'        "  ■- 

4   •   •  .  1    - 

i"  '  ■' •  •  -.."-■  .  '   .  ;    • .'  ^ 

The  nxill  hypothesis  examined  in  this  study  is  that  there  la  no 
difference  in  value  between  groups  of  simple  versus  complex  capital 
structure  firms  in  the  same  risk  class.  Before  explaining  the  procedure 
used  to  obtain  a  risk  class  sample  in  this  study,  it  would  be  useful  to 
examine  the  nature  and  objectives  of  the  risk  class  assumption. 

In  a  theoretical  sense,  MM  define  a  risk  class  as  a  group  of  firms 
whose  net  cash  earnings  before  interest  are  perfectly  correlated,  and 


-6- 

hence  differ  only  by  a  scale  factor.   "In  periods  before  t,  earnings 
and  Investments  at  t  are  uncertain;  but  for  two  firms  to  be  in  the  same 
class,  investors  must  agree  that  whatever  values  earnings  and  investment 
outlays  take  in  any  period,  for  these  two  firms  they  are  always  pro- 
portional by  the  factor  ^,  and  hence  perfectly  correlated,"  [9,  p.  161] 
However,  the  concept  is  an  ex  ante  one  and  risk  classes  are  not  directly 
observable.  •        . ,  ■ 

In  a  more  pragcatic  sense,  the  risk  class  assumption  refers  to  ,^;  c,- 
firms  with  equivalent  business  or  operating  (as  opposed  to  financial)  ■ 
risk.  The  objective  is  to  hold  operating  risk  constant  so  that  the  .  ..v;^ 
effects  of  financial  risk  can  be  observed.  But  in  this  study,  it  is 
desirable  to  hold  both  operating  risk  and  leverage,  as  defined, in  the 
usual  sense,  constant  to  determine  if  complex  capital  structure  impacts 
on  value.  ,  ■i.-f-'-    •>  -  ^f 

On  a  third  level,  the  important  objective  is  to  obtain  a  sample 
that  is  homogeneous  in  a  statistical  sense.  The  need  for  sample  homo—  ■■. 
geneity  is  summarized  by  Elton  and  Gruber  [6,  7]  who  note  three  reasons 
for  grouping  in  empirical  studies: 

(1)  To  isolate  units  that  should  in  some  sense  act  alike; 

(2)  To  hold  the  effect  of  one  or  more  omitted  variable  constant; 
.;  .;.:or  ,  ..  . ...  ^  .  .-s:^  3:.: 

(3)  To  obtain  a  homogeneous  relationship  between  the  variables 
included  in  the  model.   [6,  p.  81] 

All  three  of  these  objectives  are  necessary  in  a  valuation  study.  But 

particularly  the  second  objective  is  critical.  Elton  and  Grubar  show 

that  the  failure  to  hold  business  risk  constant  may  result  in  (1)  biased 

regression  coefficients,  (2)  biased  correlation  coefficients,  and  (3) 


-7- 

results  that  are  extremely  sample  sensitive.  The  direction  of  the  biases 
depends  on  the  relationship  between  the  omitted  variable(s)  and  those  in- 
cluded in  the  regression  equation. 

Previous  researchers  including  MM  [19,  21]  and  Barges  [1]  have  used 
Industry  samples  in  an  attempt  to  achieve  homogeneity.  But  an  Industry 
approach  is  not  possible  in  this  study  since  no  single  industry  or  group 
of  industries  provides  a  large  enough  sample  of  simple  and  complex 
capital  structure  firms.  Furthermore,  several  studies,  including  those 
of  Wippem  [30],  Gonedes  [11],  Elton  and  Gruber  [6],  and  more  recently 
by  Boness  and  Frankfurter  [4]  Indicate  that  industry  groups  are  hetero- 
genebus  with  respect  to  business  risk.  The  latter  results  are  particu- 
larly striking  in  that  firms  in  the  assumed  homogeneous  electric  utility 
industry  do  not  pass  statistical  tests  for  homogeneity,  Boness  and 
Frankfurter  conclude  that  more  parsimonious  methods  should  be  used  to 
obtain  a  risk  class  sample.  „  .  •: 

Due  to  limitations  of  the  industry  risk  class  approach,  an  alternate 
method  of  obtaining  a  sample  is  required.  Tne  objective  of  the  sampling 
procedure  is  to  select  a  sufficiently  large  and  homogeneous  group  of 
firms  from  a  piopulatlon  that  is  heterogeneous  with  respect  to  business 
risk.  The  set  of  algorithms  connnonly  referred  to  as  cluster  analysis 
techniques  seem  particularly  well  suited  to  this  purpose  and  are  used 
ifi  this  study.  Although  several  different  clustering  algorithms  are 
Available,  the  common  objective  of  most  methods  is  to  separate  a  set  of 
data  into  groups  or  clusters  that  can  be  viewed  as  contiguous  elements 
of  a  statistical  population.  The  hierarchical  methods,  a  subset  of 
cluster  analytic  techniques,  combine  objects  into  larger  and  larger 


=8- 

groups  by  minimally  increasing  some  generalized  distance  function.  The 
Euclidean  metric  is  frequently  employed,  where  the  distance  between 
points  1  and  j,  d  .  is  defined  as: 

P  1/9 

'  ^irK\    ^ik"  V^  ^'^   [8.  p.  563 

where  X.,  and  X,,  are  the  scores  of  objects  1  and  j  on  variable  k,  with 
the  summation  over  p  variables.  An  algorithm  that  utilizes  this 
Euclidean  metric  is  used  in  this  study.  .'.s-.'ii<iP'. 

Although  cluster  analysis  provides  a  method  for  obtaining  a  risk-, 
class  sample,  it  is  not  without  problems.  Issues  such  as  variable   ; 
selection,  measurement  procedures,  and  criteria  for  judging  the  results 
of  clustering  remain.  v- 

With  respect  to  grouping  variables,  accounting  risk  measures, 
market  risk  measures,  and  combinations  of  accounting  and  market  risk 
measures  are  possible  choices.  Accounting  risk  measures  (financial 
ratios)  have  long  been  used  by  analysts  in  the  security  selection  and 
evaluation  process.  In  the  present  study,  the  objective  is  to  use 
accounting  measures  to  capture  the  basic  risk  characteristics  of  com- 
panies which  should  "behave  alike"  in  the  MM  partial  equilibrium  frame- 
work. The  main  advantage  of  grouping  based  on  accounting  risk  measures 
is  that  the  approach  focuses  on  company  characteristics  evaluated  by 
the  market  in  establishing  relative  security  prices.  To  the  extent 
variables  can  be  selected  that  result  in  a  homogeneous  risk  class,  our 
knowledge  of  the  risk  determination  process  is  enhanced.  ,. 

But  there  are  several  limitations  to  the  use  of  accounting  risk 
measures.  First,  differences  in  accounting  methods  across  industries 


-9- 

and  Individual  firms  may  affect  the  conpar ability  of  riBk  measures  and 
result  In  inappropriate  groupings.   Second,  there  ia  a  lack  of  theory 
concerning  exactly  vhat  accounting  measures  to  include.  While  a 
generally  agreed  upon  list  of  risk  measures  could  be  obtained  from 
research  done  in  this  area,  there  is  always  the  danger  that  factors 
considered  Important  by  the  market  were  not  considered.  A  third  dis- 
advantage is  that  accounting  measures  lack  certain  desirable  statistical 
properties.  -  r  .  .  ^.  ,;  ,;..  .  _  .;, 

■i.i.A  currently  popular  method  of  obtaining  a  risk  class  is  to  select 
firms  with  similar  market  risk  measures.  Typically,  capital  asset   .  .  '• 
pricing  theory  is  invoked  which  assumes  that  only  systematic  risk  (beta) 
affects  security  prices  since  nonsystematic  risk  can  be  diversified 
away..  Under  the  assumption  that  financial  risk  affects  the  systsnatic 
component  of  risk,  Hamada  [13]  develops  a  method  of  unlevering  security  - 
returns.  While  Hamada's  approach  is  widely  supported  by  theory  [2,  16, 
28],  empirical  results  are  mixed.  .  ^i        .  r       .■.-^r^.. 

,.-<;..  An  appealing  approach  in  this  study  is  to  cluster  based  on  beta  and 
similar  debt-equity  ratios.   The  approach,  while  equivalent  to  Eamada's 
"and  only  slightly  more  restrictive,  avoids  an  assumption  concerning  the 
financial  risk  and  systematic  risk  relationship.    To  the  extent  non-  '■ 
systematic  risk  is  deemed  Important,  it  can  be  included  as  another 
grouping  variable. 

Regardless  of  what  set  of  variables  is  employed,  the  distance  metric 
employed  in  this  study  weights  all  sources  of  variation  equally  in  com- 
puting a  single  distance  index  between  groups.   To  the  extent  that  some 
values  are  larger  and  fluctuate  more  than  others  due  to  scale  differences. 


-10- 

greater  consideration  will  be  given  to  them.  However,  standardization 
may  result  in  dampening  sources  of  variation  that  are  particularly  good 
discriminators.  A  more  appropriate  method  of  dealing  with  the  weighting 
question  may  be  to  use  factor  analysis  to  account  for  correlations  ^mnng 
variables.  While  the  classification  of  firms  into  groups  may  be  extremely 
sensitive  to  data,  this  is  not  considered  a  problem  in  this  study  since  a 
unique  risk  class  is  not  being  sought;  all  that  is  sought  is  a  sample 
that  can  be  accepted  as  reasonably  homogeneous.  ,-:.i.c.-;  ts  ;t;:i-: 

.:  In  evaluating  the  success  of  a  particular  grouping  procedure,  the 
primary  test  concerns  how  xj'ell  the  sample  satisfies  the  assumptions  of  ' 
the  MM  risk  class  model.  Certain  statistical  tests  for  homogeneity  can  ' 

be  done;  but  to  be  valid,  the  tests  should  be  applied  to  the  valxiation  '^-- 

12 
model  directly.    Clearly,  the  determination  of  a  normative  procedure 

'for  selecting  risk  classes  would  require  the  testing  of  all  proposed  '"  -' 
methods  in  the  valuation  model.   Such  tests  are  beyond  the  scope  of  this 
study.  An  initial  concern  is  the  ability  of  a  given  set  of  variables 
to  interact  with  the  clustering  algorithm  so  as  to  obtain  relatively  large 
groups  with  little  within  group  variation.   If  several  sets  of  grouping 
variables  satisfy  this  requirement,  then  a  choice  will  be  made  on  theo- 
retical grounds.  .-j.TriaxT; 

'X.ji' ; '-. 'i.'/  iy--  ■^■^'■■■•'  '  ■   '       -  ..      -  - 

IV.  Empirical  Tests 

.  >..  ;,-.vi.  ,■  v'i- 

Sample  Selection   •    .■•!■■.'■  «■;..: I. »:;:i-i 

The  population  consisted  of  515  calendar  year-end  industrial  com- ■ 
panics  for  which:   (1)  monthly  returns  could  be  calculated  from  the 
quarterly  COMPUSTAT  file  for  the  period  February  19S7  through  December 


-11- 

1972,  and  (2)  required  financial  statement  data  was  available  from  the 
annual  CCfMFUSTAT  file  for  use  in  the  MM  model  and  in  clustering  routines. 

The  grouping  algorithm  for  t:iis  population  was  then  applied  to 

13 
various  sets  of  accounting  and  market  risk  measures.    The  most  Impor- 
tant result  was  that  all  sets  of  variables  examined  in  conjunction  with 
the  grouping  algorithm  resulted  in  some  large  clusters  of  firms  while 
maintaining  relatively  little  variation  within  groups.  While  there  was 
little  correspondence  of  groups  based  on  different  sets  of  variables, 
this   result  was  not  unexpected.  '  -  •     -.  ,--■- 

'.  '  Somewhat  aritrarily,  three  market  risk  measures  and  a  leverage  -.-:■. 
variable  were  finally  selected  as  grouping  variables.  To  obtain  the 
market  risk  measures,  monthly  rates  of  return  were  computed  for  the 
Standard  and  Poor's  Industrial  Index  for  the  1967-1972  period  and  used 
as  regressors  in  the  equation:  ,■  _^  ,  ■.,-.; 

^it  -=  ^i  -^  Vnt  •*■  ^it  l"]'    2,  ....  515'  (2) 

where:  .  ■  •.    '.  .r?-. :  -i 

r,  is  the  rate  of  return  of  company  i  in  period  t,   ••-::••:■■.;', 

a.  and  b.  are  constants,  -•"■ 

r   is  the  index  ret-urn  in  period  t,   •   .  ,  -.-.   ■.  - 

and  e.   is  a  random  disturbance. 
"■.;.-> 

The  resulting  parameter  estimates  and  mean  square  error  (nonsy sterna tic 
risk)  were  used  as  the  market  risk  measures.  The  leverage  variable  was 
computed  as  the  ratio:   (Current  Liabilities  +  Long-term  Debt  + 
Preferred  Stock)  t  Common  Equity,  using  the  average  of  annual  observa- 
tions for  1963  through  1972,  and  is  denoted  LEV-3.   In  order  to  deter- 
mine the  dilution  potential  for  the  population,  the  ratio:   shares 


-12- 

reserved  for  conversion  v  shares  outatanding  was  also  computed.   The 
average  values  and  standard  deviations  of  the  market  risk  measures,    ..: 

the  above  leverage  variable  plus  two  additional  leverage  variables, 

14 
and  dilution  potential  are  shown  in  Table  I.     .  - 

In  1972,  the  average  dilution  potential  for  the  population  averaged 
about  ten  percent.  Table  II  further  details  the  potential  dilution  from 
1963  through  1975.   The  dilution  ratio  was  generally  increasing  through 
1970  and  has  remained  fairly  constant  since  that  time.  The  fact  that 
many  companies  had  high  dilution  potential  while  others  had  relatively 
low  dilution  potential  provides  hope  that  a  risk  class  sample  containing 
both  high  and  low  dilution  companies  can  be  fonaed.  ,:.  ;■  -.'.v'^  i::- :< 

In  order  to  avoid  overweighting  particular  sources  of  variation 
and  to  account  for  corrections  f_3iong  the  risk  measures,  factor  scores 
from  the  a.,  b,,  KSE,  and  LEV-3  measures  were  used  as  input  to  the 
clustering  routine.   Table  III  shows  the  factor  analysis  results.  Three 
factors  account  for  about  75  percent  of  the  variability. 

Using  the  first  three  factor  scores  as  Inputs,  the  clustering 
algorithm  was  run  and  then  observed  at  the  point  where  the  515  firms 
had  been  coabined  into  15  groups.  Groups  sizes  ranged  from  2  to  lOA 
firms  at  this  point.  l>'hlle  several  large  clusters  were  evident,  total 
variation  within  groups  was  only  14.613  as  compared  with  total  variation 
of  254.396  for  the  population  based  on  the  factor  scores.    ,  .■-!.;.^.;:  •■{■.•.■:> 

A  group  containing  82  firms  was  chosen  as  the  cluster  from  which 
the  sample  was  obtained.   The  firms  were  then  classified  into  simple,  .  _- 
intermediate,  and  complex  categories  as  follows:     .  ■  .  :  .  i.V:JL  -i:    ■,;:.:■; 


-13- 

(1)  simple:  dilution  potential  <  6% 

(2)  intermediate:  dilution  potential  6%  >_  d.  <^  11% 

(3)  complex:   dilution  potential  >  11%. 

Klne  intermediate  firas  were  discarded,  leaving  36  complex  and  37  , 
simple  firms. 

:  .•  .  An  additional  requirement  was  the  availability  of  market  values  of 
convertible  securities  and  warrants  in  published  sources.  Ten  complex 
firms  failed  to  satisfy  this  requirement,  thus  reducing  the  usable 
complex  sample  to  26  firms.  Finally,  26  simple  firms  were  randomly   orl 
selected  in  obtaining  a  total  sample  of  52  firms.  Due  to  the  many 
restrictions  placed  on  the  population  and  on  the  sample,  a  caveat  Is 
in  order  when  generalizing  from  the  results  of  tests. 

Table  IV  details  the  market  risk  leverage,  dilution,  and  size 
characteristics  of  the  simple  and  complex  groups.   There  is  no  signifi- 
cant difference  in  the  market  risk  measures  for  the  two  groups.    ,  .■^•.•'• 
However,  the  attempt  to  obtain  a  sample  that  was  equally  levered  for 
the  two  groups  was  not  successful.  The  complex  group's  debt  to  equity 
ratio  of  1.06  was  significantly  higher  than  the  simple  group's  ratio 
'of  .902.    This  result  may  indicate  that  complex  capital  structure 
firms  are  in  general  more  highly  levered  than  simple  capital  structure 
firms.  The  importance  of  this  difference  in  leverage  must  be  judged 
when  evalutlng  the  test  results. 

The  most  Important  result  of  the  sample  selection  process  was  that 
a  substantial  difference  in  dilution  potential  was  achieved.  The  com- 
plex group's  dilution  potential  averaged  about  25%  compared  with  only 
3%  for  the  simple  group. 


-14- 

One  difference  betveen   the  two   groupa   is  average  firm  size,   as 
measured  by  total  assets  in  1972.      The  simple  group's  average  total 
assets  of  $1,002  billion  is  about  fifty  percent  larger  than  the  complex 
group's  average  of   $.667  billion.     Further  consideration  is  given  to 
the  effects  of  size  later. 

Comparing  Table  IV  with  Table  I,   note   that   the  average  risk  measures 
for  the  sample  are  close  to  the  population  values.     However,    the  vari- 
ability of   the  sample  risk  neasurea  is  substantially  less   than  that  of    ,^   ,. 
the  population.     This  provides  evidence  of   the  homogeneity  resulting        .., 
from  the  clustering  procedure.  *    ..-  •  -j    f^. 

Model  Selection 

The  familiar  MM  valuation  model  expresses   total  market  value  as: 

-.     .n:T;V.  V  =-ix(l-T)  +  tD  +  l<^a-r)f^fx^lT  (3)    [21.  p.  344] 

where:       ^■'•■■■^^■■■■■'   i-:;  ■;.•■■?    • -'   =.--■. ^     ■  .    ^  .,    ■  ^    j^.^. 

V  -   total  market  value  of  the  firm  ,  .-. 

—  ■»=  the  appropriate  capitalization  rate  for  uncertain  pure 
_   equity  earning  streams  for  the  risk  class  *  c v.j  at; s 

X  =  expected  average  annual  earnings  before  interest  and  tax 
X   =  the  marginal  tax  rate  .  ..  ;  ,  r.j;is~ 

D  =  the  market  value  of  debt 

k  =  the  earnings  growth  rate  '  ".'-'O?"',  "?:•-» 

p*  =  the  rate  of  retvurn  on  growth  opportunities 
C  =  the  cost  of  capital,  and  i ,  r .;         ,  •  =--•«•--  ^.-r-j^^- 

T  =  the  duration  of  growth. 

Econometric  analogs  of  model  (3)  provided  the  basis  for  the  1966  MM 

tests  and  are  also  used  in  this  study  for  testing  hypotheses  concerning 

the  effects  of  complex  capital  structure  on  value.   The  following  three 

models  are  employed: 


-15- 


V-xD  =  a^  +  a^x""^  +  a^G  +  u  (A)    [21,    p.  348] 


T^  =  «1  ■*•  -0  v4d  ^  V=?D  -^  -  <^>    t21,   p.   349] 

^=^0X-^^1?^^2!^-  (6)    [21,    p.  350] 


All  three  codels  are  now  expressed   in  the  form  of  first  order,  normal 
error,  multiple  regression  models.     Model    (A)   is   the  econometric  analog 
of  model   (3),   with  the  growth  tern  G  simplified.     Model   (5)   is   the  "yield" 
formulation  of  model  (A),  where  a|   =•  p.     tSodel   (6)   is  the  deflated  ver- 
sion of  model   (A),   where  A  is  the  book  value  of  assets.      The  model  was  ..^^ 
suggested  as  a  means  of  implementing  the  weighted  least  squares  approach, 
under   the  assumption  that   the  source  of  heteroscedasticity  is  firm  size. 

Dates  of  Tests 

An  objective  was   to   test  hypotheses  at  various  points  in  the  busi- 
ness cycle.     Conmon  stock  prices  were  generally  increasing  in  the  early 
1970*s  and  reached  a  peak  in  December- January  1972-1973.      Stock  prices 
generally  fell  after  1973  and  reached  low  levels  at  the  end  of  197A. 
In  contrast,   long-term  bond  prices  were  relatively  flat  in  the  early 
1970's  but  then  started  to  fall  rapidly  in  1973,    reaching  a  low  in  the 
third  quarter  of  197A. 

The  test  dates  were  chosen  as  January   31,    1973,    197A,   and   1975 
to  reflect   stock  price  peaks,   midpoints,    and    troughs  respectively.      The 
January  31st  dates  were  chosen  to  avoid  any  possible  year-end  price 
aberations  and   so   that   the  previous  year's   earnings  number  would  be 


-16- 


better  known  by   the  market.     D&tes  close  to  year-ends  were  chosen  to 
avoid  measureaient  errors  resulting  from  poet  year-end  capital  structure 


changes. 


Variable  Definition 

The  details  of   Che  capital  structures  of   the  52  firms  comprising 
the  sample  were  obtained  as  of   1972,   1973,   and  1974  year-ends.      The 
variables  in  model  (4)  were  then  operationally  measured  as   follows: 
'•"-V.     represents   the  total  market  value  of  firm  i  at  the   time  t 
and  consists  of   the  market  value  of  all  securities  and  other  claims 
against   the  assets  of  the  firm.     Market  prices  of  common  stock,  warrants, 

most  convertible  securities  and  preferred  stock  issues  were  obtained 

19 
, from  published  sources. 

,£,.!'-  Based  on  a  pilot  study  on  a  smaller  sample  of   28  firms,    it  was 

determined    that  all  non-convertible  long-term  debt  could  be  measured 

20 

at  book  value  without  significantly  affecting  the  results.    Conver- 
tible securities  and  warrants  were  measured  at  market  values.  All 
other  liabilities,  primarily  current  liabilities  and  deferred  taxes, 
were  included  at  their  book  values. 

The  expected  cash  savings  due  to  the  tax  deductibility  of  interest 
payments,  tD,  was  computed  at  48%  of  the  book  value  of  long-term  debt. 
It  should  be  noted  that  to  the  extent  the  market  views  the  issuance  of 
a  convertible  security  as  an  expectation  that  the  firm  will  unlever, 
the  operational  definition  of  the  tax  savings  is  upward  biased  for  the 

complex  group. 

—1 
The  tax-adjusted  earnings  term,  X  ,  was  computed  from  CQMPUSTAT 

data  as  operating  earnings  less  taxes  (COJIPUSTAT  variable  numbers  (13-14) 


-17- 

-16).  The  current  year's  earnings  was  used  under  the  assumption  that 
the  process  generating  the  annual  accounting  earnings  number  approxi- 
mates a  randon  walk  [32,  33]. 

Finally  the  growth  term,  G,  was  measured  as  in  the  1966  MM  study 
using  the  4-year  linear  growth  rate  of  assets  times  the  current  year's 
assets.  While  this  operational  definition  is  not  a  good  proxy  for 

growth  in  the  true  sense,  the  election  was  made  to  follow  MM  due  to 

21                  -.<='■   ■'  -.<.:• 
lack  of  a  better  measure.  ;  . ' 

HycothesiH  Testing 

Using  models  C4) ,  (5) ,  and  (6)  a  variety  of  approaches  are  available 
for  testing  for  differences  in  value  between  the  simple  and  complex 
groups.  One  approach  is  to  add  a  dummy  variable  or  series  of  dummy 
variables  representing  complex  capital  structure  to  the  models  and  test 
the  coefficient (s)  for  significance.  A  second  approach  is  to  run  sep- 
arate regressions  for  the  simple  and  complex  groups  and  test  for  differ- 
ences in  regression  lines.  A  third  approach  is  to  test  for  differences 
in  the  average  residuals  of  the  two  groups  using  an  analysis  of  variance 
•approach.  Essentially,  these  techniques  ere  equivalent  and  will  be  ' 
subject  to  the  same  econometric  problems.       "     ..•.-•  ... 

.  '  Due  to  its  ability  to  examine  several  effects  simultaneously,  and 
because  of  its  relative  parsimony  with  respect  to  theory,  an  analysis 
of  variance  model,  using  residuals  from  the  two  groups  as  data,  was 
preferred  in  this  study. 

Consider  the  following  niodel: 


-18- 


\jk  =  VJ--  +  «!  +  Pj  +  (ag)^^   +  e^j,^  (7)    [25,   p.  568] 


1  »  1,    2,   3 

J  =  1,    2 

k—  1,    2,    •••(   26 


where: 


y..   is  an  overall  constant 

a     is   the  time  effect   (years  1972,   1973,   and  1974) 

0.    is   the  capital  structure  effect    (simple  or  complex) 

(ttg)        is   the  interaction  effect 

k  is  the  number  of  replicates. 


I_      U..i:lJ. 


The  Y,  ,  ^s  are  residuals  from  the  regressions  and  are  assumed  indepen- 
dent N(u..  +  a^  +  B  +  (a8)^.)a^  [25,  p.  569].^^ 

Using  model  (7),  it  is  possible  to  test  for  differences  in  value 
between  the  simple  and  complex  groups  by  examining  the  following  oper- 
ational hypotheses: 

H^   Hiere  is  no  difference  in  average  residuals  over  the  three 
-  .,       year  period . 

Kj  There  is  no  difference  in  the  average  residuals  of  the 
simple  versus  complex  groups. 

-?:./.   1  "•- 

H   There  is  no  interaction  between  time  and  capital  structure 

effects. 
Note  that  the  use  of  least  squares  estimators  in  models  (A),  (5), 
and  (6)  rules  out  rejecting  K.  since  the  residuals  must  sxim  to  zero  In 
any  one  time  period.  But  the  use  of  the  two-way  design  provides  a  con- 
venient accuracy  check  on  the  data,  and  more  Importantly,  allows  for 
testing  Interactions.  ..        .. 

Results 

Table  V   summarizes    the   estimates  obtained  using  model    (4)   for    the 
combined   52-flrm  san^le.      The  earnings  and   growth  coefficients  are 
significant  in  all  three  years  while   the  constant   is  not  significantly 


-19- 

dlfferent  from  zero.  The  values  of  the  coefficients  seem  reasonably 
consistent  with  the  underlying  theory. 

Plots  of  residuals  on  the  estimated  values  of  the  dependent  vari- 
able appear  in  Table  VI.  The  plots  show  evidence  of  heteroscedastlclty, 
but  there  is  little  evidence  that  a  linear  regression  function  is  not 
appropriate.  A  possible  concern  is  the  presence  of  some  outliers. 
Standardizing  residuals  in  terms  of  the  residual  standard  deviation 
(mTsTET) "  from  model  (A),  and  treating  deviations  in  excess  of  2,5 
standard  deviations  as  outliers,  several  outliers  are  noted  each  year. 
In  1972  and  1973,  Phillips  Petroleum  (44  s.d.),  Texas  Instruments    '  - 
C+3  s.d.)  and  Goodyear  (-2,5  s.d.)  are  outliers.  In  1974,  Phillips 
Petroleum  and  Texas  Instruments  again  appear,  along  vrith  Bristol  Myers 
and  Union  Carbide.  The  outliers  all  belong  to  the  simple  group  and  are 
some  of  the  larger  firms  in  the  sample.       '^  " .'  '    '  *"■     '  '•■•''■■'■- 

To  assure  that  a  few  large  firms  were  not  influencing  the  results*' 
model  (4)  was  rerun,  using  a  reduced  sample  of  the  twenty  smallest 
companies  from  each  of  the  two  groups.  This  procedure  had  the  added  "• 
advantage  of  eliminating  the  previous  noted  average  size  difference  -''* 
of  the  two  groups.  The  regression  results  are  shown  in  Table  VII.  It. 
is  evident  that  the  estimates  are  not  unduly  influenced  by  the  large   • 
firms.  The  earnings  and  growth  coefficients  are  consistent  with  the  '  '"' 
previous  results.  But  the  fit  is  somewhat  better  as  evidenced  by 
smaller  standard  deviations,  generally  higher  T-statistics  and  higher 
R  values.  ^ 

Models  (5)  and  (6)  were  suggested  variance- stabilizing  transfor- 
mations of  the  basic  valuation  model.  Estimates  for  these  models  are 
sho^m  in  Tables  VIII  and  IX  respectively. 


-20- 

Model  (5)  Is  the  "yield"  formulation  of  model  (4),  where  the  con- 
stant al   provides  the  estimate  of  p.  The  reciprocal  of  the  constant 

^  ■•.-•..'  "j 

term  is  equivalent  to  the  estimated  earnings  capitalization  rate  in  model 
(A) .  Compared  with  Tables  V  and  VII,  the  reciprocal  valxies  are  all  higher, 
but  the  direction  of  change  over  time  is  consistent  with  the  previous  re- 
suits.  As  in  the  MM  study,  the  explanatory  power  of  model  (5)  applied 
to  this  sample  is  much  lower  than  for  the  non-deflated  model. 

The  residual  plots  for  model  (5)  are  presented  in  Table  X.  The— ^  . 
residuals  appear  particularly  well-behaved  with  an  apparent  random 
distribution  about  zero  and  no  evidence  of  heteroscedasticity.  Only 
one  outlier  is  noted.  Stone  Container,  in  1974.   ,   ..  ,  :        ^  , 

.  .,  Hbdel  (6)  is  the  deflated  form  of  model  (4),  where  the  deflatex 
is  book  value  of  assets.  The  explanatory  power  of  this  model  when 
employed  by  tM,  using  a  utility  sample,  was  relatively  high..  Uut  this 
is  not  the  case  in  the  present  study  and  there  is  other  evidence  of 
model  mlsspeclfication.  This  is  clear  from  the  residual  plots,  shown 
in  Table  XI.  There  is  a  noticeable  doimward  drift  in  the  residuals  for 
higher  values  of  the  dependent  variable.  This  effect  is  especially 
noticeable  in  the  1974  plot  and  may  indicate  a  violation  of  the  lin-.  .• 
earity  assumption,  the  effect  of  an  omitted  variable,  or  some  other 
mlsspeclfication.   ,  ,  .,„ 

The  following  conclusions  seem  warranted  concerning  the  adequacy 
of  the  sample  and  models  examined.  It  seems  that  a  relatively  homo- 
geneous sample  has  been  obtained  using  the  clustering  procedure.  This 
is  evidenced  by  high  explanatory  power  of  model  (4),  coefficients  that 
are  consistent  with  the  theory,  and  evidence  that  the  estimators  are  not 

'   '    '   '  ■  ■   i.i   -y 


-21- 

very  sample  sensitive.  Sample  homogeneity  implies  that  the  average 
results  of  the  cross-sectional  tests  are  due  to  the  entire  sample, 
rather  than  due  to  the  influence  of  just  a  few  firms. 

A  concern  was  the  average  size  difference  between  the  simple  and 
complex  firms.  In  the  presence  of  heteroscedasticity,  the  size  differ- 
ence la  Important,  since  It  could  lead  to  rejecting  the  null  hypothesis 
for  thi.s  reason  alone.  The  use  of  the  reduced  sample  for  model  (4)  and 
the  deflated  model  (5)  have  apparently  purged  the  results  of  the  effect 
of  size  differences,  but  model  C6)  inay  be  oisspecified.  --.■..;.  .-i;...^, 
'*"■   The  results  of  hypothesis  testing  using  the  analysis  of  variance 

i^del  (7)  appear  in  Tables  XII vand  XIII.  Note  that  time  is  not  a  slg- 

24 
nlf leant  effect  and  that  there  is  no  significant  interaction.    However, 

for  all  models  tested,  capital  structure  is  a  highly  significant  effect. 
Note  the  direction  of  the  difference  between  groups.  Except  for  the 
deflator,  models  (4)  and  (6)  are  equivalent.  The  residuals  using  these 
models  are  consistently  negative  for  the  complex  group  and  positive  for 
the  simple  group.  In  other  ^«3rds,  the  observed  market  values  for  the 
compilex  firms  consistently  fell  below  the  estimated  value  and  the  simple 
,  firms  above.  The  results  from  model  (5)  are  consistent  with  the  other 
models.  Since  model  C^)  is  the  yield  formulation  of  model  (4),  consis- 
tency requires  that  complex  firms  sell  at  higher  yields  (lower  values) 

25 
than  the  simple  firms,  as  the  results  indicate.         ..,.., 

Discussion 

The  test  results  indicating  that  complex  capital  structure  firms 
were  valued  lower  by  the  market  than  risk  equivalent  simple  capital 
structure  firms  was  a  surprising  result  and  one  that  is  contrary  to  the 


-22- 

underlying  theory  and  conventional  wisdom.  For  this  reason,  a  variety 
of  additional  steps  vere  taken  to  assure  that  the  results  were  not  due 
to  using  different  measurement  procedures  for  the  two  groups  or  due  to 
perceived  risk  differences. 

In  regard  to  possible  neasuremant  differences,  the  following  steps 
were  taken.  Off  balance  sheet  financing  (leases)  were  valued  and  in- 
cluded in  measuring  the  dependent  variable.  Four  simple  and  five  coa-  - 

plex  firms  had  substantial  amounts  of  leases.  Another  concern  was  a 

26 
possible  overstatement  of  the  tax  savings  from  convertible  debt.  ..  ■   >.. 

The  dependent  variable  was  recalculated  for  the  complex  group  under  the 
assumption  that  the  tax  savings  from  convertible  debt  was  zero.  Finally, 
convertible  debt  was  originally  computed  at  market  value,  while  all 
other  debt  was  computed  at  book  value.  Kow  measuring  convertible  debt 
at  book  Value,  and  along  with  the  other  changes,  the  models  were  rerun. 
Conclusions  based  on  the  revised  measures  were  unchanged. 

A  second  concern  was  the  procedure  used  to  calculate  the  market 
risk  measures.  These  were  calculated  using  historical  return  series 
under  the  assumption  of  stationarity.  Perhaps  the  risk  characteristics 
■  of  the  simple  and  complex  groups  differed  en  an  ex  post  basis  which 
woxild  account  for  the  observed  difference  in  value.  To  investigate  this 
possibility,'  the  market  risk  measures  were  recalculated  at  the  end  of 
1973,  1974,  and  1975  using  the  seventy-one  most  recent  monthly  obser- 
vations prior  to  the  respective  year-ends.  Although  there  were  a  few 
anomalies  in  the  results,  a  geaer.\l  conclusion  is  that  the  two  groups 

did  not  differ  significantly  in  terms  of  market  risk  measures  for  the 

' L    4  J  27 
ex  post  periods. 


-23- 

There  are  several  possible  explanations  for  the  difference  in  value. 
One  conclusion  is  that  the  difference  is  evidence  of  market  inefficiency. 
Based  on  test  resxilts,  investors  should  have  sold  their  portion  of  the 
more  highly  valued  simple  capital  structure  firms,  reinvesting  in  com- 
plex capital  structure  firms,  to  obtain  the  same  expected  earnings 
stream  at  a  lower  cost.  But  while  market  inefficiency  is  a  possible  ex- 
planation, it  seems  unlikely  that  such  large  and  significant  differences 
In  value  could  have  persisted  over  the  three  year  period  observed. 

To  assist  in  providing  an  alternate  explanation.  Tables  XIV  and  XV 
summarize,  as  of  January  31,  1973,  valuation  data  for  convertible  bonds 
and  convertible  preferred  stock  included  in  the  sample.  Although 
January  31,  1973  was  near  a  stock  market  peak,  few  of  the  convertible 
seciflrities  were  selling  at  premiums.   In  fact,  most  of  the  convertible 
debt  issues  x;ere  selling  below  book  values.  Although  not  shown,  this 
disparity  betv;een  book  values  and  market  values  became  much  greater  in 
1973  as  Interest  rates  continued  to  rise. 

Analysis  of  the  issue  dates  of  the  complex  securities  indicated 
that  a  high  majority  were  issued  in  the  middle  to  late  1960*8.  Empir- 
ically, it  is  known  tliat  conversion  generally  occurs  within  five  to 
seven  years  fro^i  issue  date,  or  not  at  all.  By  the  end  of  1973,  or 
perhaps  earlier,  it  became  obvious  that  any  hoped  for  conversion  was 
not  forthcoming.  Thus,  for  the  test  period,  the  market  generally  viewfed 
the  complex  securities  as  overhanging  issues.  .   ...... 

To  the  extent  there  is  a  cost  to  the  firm  associated  with  over- 
hanging Issues,  this  cost  would  explain  the  observed  difference  in  value. 
The  complex  firms  were  already  more  highly  levered  than  the  simple  firms 


-24- 

and  may  seek  a  lower  debt/equity  ratio  in  the  future.  If  equity  is 
issued  in  an  atteapt  to  nove  toward  a  lower  target  debt  level,  the  issue 
may  only  be  marketable  at  a  relatively  high  cost  to  the  firm.  If  the 
target  is  achieved  by  calling  the  convertible  securities,  the  cost  of 
the  required  funds  nay  also  be  high.  la  sunmary,  there  are  real  costs 
associated  with  the  loss  of  financing  flexibility  due  to  overhanging 
Issues,  The  market  is  not  ignoring  these  costs. 

Another  anomaly  in  the  results  is  the  leverage  difference  between 
groups  without  a  corresponding  difference  in  market  risk  measures.  This 
relationship  is  inconsistent  with  Hamada's  argument  that  beta  is  a  func- 
tion of  leverage.  The  difference  in  leverage  tended  to  increase  from 
1973  to  1975.  As  an  explanation  of  the  difference  in  value,  the  higher 
levered  complex  firms  may  offer  a  higher  risk  of  bankruptcy.  But  this 
suggestion  is  not  appealing,  since  ex  ante  bankruptcy  costs  are  believed 

to  be  small  US]-  "  .  i;.-.;c::. 

In  concluding  this  section,  a  statement  seems  necessary  concerning 
possible  measurement  error  in  the  independent  variables.   Since  observa- 
tions on  true  earnings  and  growth  are  not  available,  it  is  known  that 
'  parameter  estimates  for  the  valuation  equations  are  biased  and  the  :-:- 
measurement  error  will  be  impounded  in  the  residuals.  However,  para- 
meter estimation  was  not  a  primary  objective  in  this  study.  Unless 
there  is  a  difference  in  bias  between  the  simple  and  complex  groups, 
and  there  is  no  reason  to  expect  this  to  occur,  the  test  results  should 
be  unaffected  by  the  presence  of  measurement  error.       .  ^ 


-25- 


V.   Conclusion 


This  study  has  attenipted  to  extand  previous  tests  of  the  risk  class 
model  by  examining  the  effects  of  complex  capital  structure.  The  major 
research  finding  was  that,  within  a  risk  class  sample,  a  group  of  complex 
capital  structure  companies  was  valued  lower  than  a  group  of  simple  cap- 
ital structure  companies.  This  occurred  over  a  three-year  cross  sec- 
tional test  period  when  there  was  little  expectation  that  complex  secur- 
ities would  be  converted. 

Assiuning  the  theory  is  correct,  the  sample  can  be  accepted  as  a  "■■ 
homogeneous  risk  class,  and  assuming  that  the  always  present  danger  of 
measurement  errors  did  not  affect  the  results,  two  possible  explanations 
for  the  results  were  suggested.  One  explanation,  market  inef ficiencyj 
is  unlikely  to  have  persisted  over  the  test  period.  The  other  explana- 
tion, future  coats  associated  with  correcting  capital  structure  to  a 
lower  target  debt/equity  ratio  for  the  complex  group,  is  a  more  likely 
explanation. 

A  limitation  of  the  study  is  that  convertible  securities  were  eval- 
uated in  a  period  when  conversion  was  not  expected.   It  would  be  inter- 
esting to  repeat  the  tests  in  periods  when  convertible  securities  are 
selling  at  substantial  premiums. 

Methodologically,  cluster  analysis  seems  to  provide  a  useful  pro- 
cedure for  obtaining  a  homogeneous  risk  class  sample.   The  method  pro- 
vides a  useful  alternative  to  the  well-known  industry  and  beta  adjustment 
approaches. 

M/B/151 


l-t 


0  S  g 

>   O   < 

«    M    Eh 

M   tn   w 
W    K    H 

g^g 

2 

w  O  v: 

•x 

§^§ 

* 

CD 

<  si  < 

0 

n 

a:  o  2: 

rH 

iH 

w   t,   W 

• 

• 

OU 


1 

a.    ,^. 

> 

« 

K 

*      • 

Z 

1; 

>J 

D   i4 

0 

•           • 

§ 

M 

ro 

m 

0) 

frt    U 

D 

CM 

CD 

0 

• 

0 

Oi 

CTl 

r- 

•H- 

J    + 

u 

W 

« 

4J 

U 

•H 

•<• 

■P 

a 

•      • 

s 

1: 

•iJ 

<V 

Q  uy 

0 

w 

1 

•         « 

M 

y3 

en 

> 

H    (X, 

s 

P 

^ 

n 

>i  w 

U 

• 

0 

0; 

•5t 

UT 

4J    0 

»J 

J    + 

u 

w 

• 

• 

•H    -W 

X    c 

0    (0 

<• 

rH      ft 

c.  e 

•   Z 

> 

s  0 

iH 

D   0 

H 

0  0 

I 

H   1 

M 

OvJ 

ro 

u 

> 

3 

0 

lO 

-o 

w 

•   0 

CV 

■^ 

T 

>«  c 

»-] 

tJ   0 

w 

« 

0   K 

0)    V4 

0)  m 

> 

CO 

>^   0 

W 

*z 

tr>  >. 

Q 

^ 

in 

ifl 

a 

fc 

D 

i-H 

vo 

Q    U 

Q  0 

H 

"C 

r- 

(3 

Eh 

§ 

• 

•d  -o 

cn 

0> 

CM 

c  c 

(3    0 

r-i 

«    *0 

(u  0 

ra 

-H 

en 

r-l 

r^ 

(tS      - 

* 

CO 

in 

M    rH 

W 

• 

« 

G}  <a 

^ 

<N 

nH 

>  -H 

r- 

in 

u  u 

•J  -p 

* 

w 

0 

* 

_ 

«  0 
J4  ns 

SS 

m   C 

0  p 

W    Eh 
A.   2 

r^ 

•^^ 

CO 

in 

X  0 

g 

• 

(1)    U1 

a; 

k 

« 

S 

<t 

0 

cn 

>D 

en 

« 

H 

>* 

<4 

•H 

• 

rr 

Vt 

^ 

F-( 

0) 

> 

, 

< 

* 

CM 

,     --• 

• 

1  'i 

1 

> 

Q 

Q 
Eh 

T! 

0 

•H 

^J 

<U 

>-l 

O, 

(1) 

c 

>. 

x; 

I 

+j 

0 

s^ 

0 

a; 

IH 

•u 

W 

c 

V( 

0 

0 

•H 

<+^ 

4J 

<d 

m 

> 

OJ 

n 

en 

0 

nJ 

V) 

n 

XX 

0) 

0 

> 

n 

g 

2 

0 

«J 

^ 

<D 

w 

^ 

(1) 

«W 

:3 

0 

0) 

m 

4J 

e 

(0 

w 

> 

nJ 

l-< 

M 

x: 

OJ 

u 

> 

c 

<u 

g 

CJ       - 

.     f-H 

r- 

g 

c 

0 

IN 

Tl 

(^ 

<U 

cn 

(fl 

r-t 

w 

(fl 

•H 

(N 

A 

u 

ff! 

r^ 

0 

>1 

CT^ 

a; 

% 

r-) 

M 

5h 

flj 

rJ 

0 

g 

^ 

0 

10 

0    • 

0    <N 

0 

M 

0 

Q  r- 

!-l 

>, 

CO 

y 

cr. 

0 

• 

A  '-<■ 

4J 

M 

tn 

cn 

0 

0 

II 

iC 

o  x: 

(8 

iw 

CJ 

0    cr> 

<w 

c 

e 

)^    3 

0 

(0 

x:   0 

C 

t7> 

Ai 

■u  v< 

•W 

<C 

£ 

w 

x: 

+J 

•H 

r»  +j 

■O 

C 

X 

Sh 

to 

(1) 

(U 

<u 

cr»  n 

w 

0 

-c 

4J 

rH    vD 

:3 

u 

c 

0 

cr^ 

0) 

•H 

a; 

^-^ 

t? 

Oi 

K( 

0 

c 

K 

m  T) 

.-1 

Oi 

0 

E 

3   0 

-§ 

CP 

vi  -a 

IS 

'O 

0 

X(  u 

•H 

u 

&) 

^ 

0   0 

M 

(U 

w 

fa    Oj 

Ifl 

> 

(3 

> 

< 

CQ 

O 

•» 

« 

* 

4J 

« 

g 

-27- 


TABLE  II 


Shares  Reserved  for  Conversion  As  a  Per  Cent  of  Outstanding  Shares 

515  Industrial  Firms 


>50%   >40%   >30%   >20%   >10%   TOTAL 


1963 


1964 


195  5 


1966 


1957 


1963 


1969 


1970 


1971 


1972 


1973 


1974 


1975 


Nun±)er 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

1 

.02 

6 
1.1 

7 
1.4 

17 
3.3 

49 
8.0 

515 

NuirjDer 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

1 
.02 

6 
1.2 

8 
1.6 

16 
3.1 

51 
9.9 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

2 

.04 

6 
1.2 

8 
1.6 

20 
3.9 

50 
9.7 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

3 

.06 

9 
1.7 

11 
2.1 

24 
4.7 

57 
11.1 

515 

Hinrber 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

5 

1.0 

15 
2.9 

22 
4.3 

43 
8.3 

90 
17.5 

515 

Nunber 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

8 
1.6 

18 
3.5 

29 
5.6 

53 
10.3 

112 
21.7 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

8 

.  1-5 

17 
3.3 

28 
5.4 

57 
11.6 

127 
24.7 

515  . 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

12 

2.3 

21 
4.1 

44 
8.5 

83 
16.2 

162 

31.5 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

14 
2.7 

22 
4.3 

39 
7.6 

75 
14.9 

172 
33.4 

515 

Nuirber 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

9 

1.7 

22 

4.3 

*3B 
7.4 

75 

14.6 

167 
32.4 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

9 
1.7 

20 
3.9 

39 
7.6 

78 
15.1 

175 
34.0 

515 

Niimber 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

9 

1,7 

20 
3.9 

36 
7.0 

32 
15.9 

170 
33.1 

515 

Number 

Per  Cent  of  Total 

9 

1.7 

21 
4.1 

34 
6.6 

74 
14.4 

171 
33.2 

515 

-28- 


TABLE    III 


SiOTinary  Factor  Analysis  Statistic^ 
Alpha,   Beta,   M.S.E.,    and  LEV-3 


Correlation  Matrix 


ALPHA 

BETA 

M.S.E. 

LEV-3 

1 

2 

3 

4 

1 

1.00000 

- 

2 

-0.35347 

1.00000 

3 

0.01813 

0.40780 

1.00000 

4 

-0.12980 

0.30450 

0.18031 

1.00000 

1.44159 


0.82411 


Eigenvalues 
.0.70545 


0.00114 


0.36040 


Cumulative  Proportion  of  Total  Variance 
0,56642  0.74279  0.74307 


VARIABLE 

1 

•  2 

3 

4 


ESTIMATED  COMMUKALITY 

0-823072 

0.404411 

;  ,- -  0.762258 

0.982558 


FINAL  COMMUNALITY 

0.822933 
0.40  3622 
0.762050 
0.982537 


-29- 

TABLE   IV 
Market  Risk  and  Other  Characteristics  of  Sanqple 


COMPLEX  GROUP 


GROUPING  VARIABLES 


FIRM  NW-IE 

^i 

H 

MSE 
38.8 

LEV-3 
.883 

'  DIL.  ? 
.13 

:      SIZE* 

Amax 

-.025 

.711 

1408 

Greyhound 

-.281 

1.136 

28.4 

1.069 

.35 

1444 

National  Distillers 

-.377 

.703 

30.3 

.951 

.12 

966 

Cluett  Peabody 

-,324 

1.246 

47,2 

1.190 

.15 

316 

Wayne  Go s sard 

-.273 

1.119 

63.3 

1.180 

.57 

40 

Fibreboard 

-.029 

1.194 

73.8 

1.450 

.51 

182 

Monsanto 

-.216 

1.126 

31.9 

.750 

.13 

2236 

Stauffer  Chemical 

-.275 

1.210 

35.3 

.660 

.14 

578 

Witco  Chemical 

-.389 

1.636 

48.2 

1.253 

.25 

229 

Lone  Star  Industries 

-.072 

1.640 

55.9 

.747 

.18 

449 

Medusa  Corp. 

.085 

1.369 

51.6 

.640 

.17 

143 

Interpace  Corp. 

-.504 

1.402 

53.8 

1.340 

.37 

158 

Annco  Steel 

-.349 

.987 

30.5 

.720 

.15 

2082 

Crane  Co. 

-.208 

1.234 

44.2 

1.540 

.41 

573 

Cooper  Industries 

.007 

1.511 

80.7 

1.160 

.43 

214 

Otis  Elevator 

-.112 

.691 

29.8 

.740 

.18 

572 

'  Scovill  Mft. 

-.191 

1.488 

44.3 

1.160 

.43 

318 

Singer 

-.003 

1.123 

28.3 

1.520 

.26 

1608 

Fruehauf 

-.118 

1.255 

48.7 

1.150 

.19 

556 

Eaton 

-.078 

1.549 

40.3 

.810 

.13 

947 

Ainfac 

.715 

1.294 

57.9 

1.280 

.20 

560 

Host  International 

.399 

1.445 

64.1 

1.080 

.15 

82 

GAF  Corp. 

-.544 

1.223 

63.5 

1.202 

.50 

610 

Copperweld  Corp. 

-.036 

1.109 

64.2 

.718 

.12 

83 

Interstate  Brands 

-.069 

.524 

68.8 

.937 

.14 

98 

GATX 

.004 

1.023 

76.5 

1.468 

.11 

864 

Average 

-.126 

1.191 

50.5 

1.06 

.25 

667 

Standard  Deviation 

.264 

.291 

15.96 

.282 

.14  • 

620 

*  Book  value  of  total  assets  for  1972. 


-30- 


TASLS    IV 
Market  Risk  and  Other  Characteristics  of  Sample 


SE-IPLE   GROUP 


GROUPING  ^/ARIABLES 


FIRM  NAME 

-^ 

1.428 

MSE 
84.8 

LEV-3 
1.415 

OIL.  % 
.03 

SIZE  * 

Eastern  Gas 

,014 

482 

Sante  Fe  International 

.525 

1.885 

83.4 

1.189 

.04 

185 

Domtrir  Ltd- 

.016 

1.057 

57.7 

.376 

.00 

503 

Stone  Container 

.192 

.880 

69.4 

.649 

.00 

73  . 

Union  Carbide 

-.432 

1.073 

16.9 

.763 

.00 

3718 

Koppers  Co. 

.080 

1-028 

44.1 

.832 

.01 

470 

Bristol  Myers 

-.175 

.948 

29.3 

1.241 

.05 

2560 

Ansul  Co. 

.310 

1.054 

97.8 

1.061 

.06 

48 

Marathon  Oil 

■  -.220 

1.243 

46.9 

.655 

.02 

1514 

Phillips  Petroleum 

.503 

1.141 

62.0 

.647 

.00 

3269 

Robertson         <•  . 

-.174 

1-050 

75.4 

.915 

.03 

133 

Goodyear 

.080 

1.066 

28. 3 

.953 

.03 

3980 

American  Can 

-.541 

.714 

25.6 

.831 

.05 

1491 

Continental  Can 

-.186 

-830 

34.5 

.702 

.05 

1574 

Carborundum 

.102 

1.188 

52.8 

.565 

.06 

308 

Owens  Corning 

-.001 

1.107 

45.3 

.588 

.04 

533 

Hoadaille       •.  -■-- 

-.007 

1-448 

52.8 

.993 

.02 

159 

Honeywell 

-.199 

1-932 

152.7 

1.259 

.06 

2240 

Texas  Instr^jments 

.037 

1.240 

41.6 

.741 

.06 

534 

A.  0.  Smith 

.335 

1.314 

41.7 

.700 

.06 

302 

ACF  Industries 

.182 

.692 

78.8 

1.015 

.03 

179 

Pullman 

-.190 

.917 

35.1 

.855 

.03 

509 

H.  K.  Porter 

-.340 

.588 

42.6 

1.245 

.00 

151 

G.  C.  Murphy     ^  . 

-.088 

1.035 

45.7 

-464 

.02 

188 

Kroger 

-.349 

1.062 

43.4 

1.117 

.00 

811 

Servisco 

.301 

.834 

102.4 

1.172 

.03 

36 

Average 

Standard  Deviation 


-.009        1.108  57.346      .902  .03  1002 

.273  .313  29.629      .253  .02  1191 


*  Book  value  of  total  assets   for   1972- 


-31- 


ThHLF.   V 

Estiniates  From  Model     f4) 
52-Firm  Combined  Sample 


Year  a_ 


1972  64.073 

Standard  deviation  78.116 

T  statistic  .82 

R'^  .85 


^1 

^2 

16.138* 

1.477* 

1.273 

.577 

12.67 

2.56 

1973 

76.801 

12.269* 

1.616^ 

Standard  deviation 

98.911 

1.285 

.815 

T  statistic 
R 

.45 

9.54 

1.98 

.78 

1974 

68.933 

7.685* 

2.695* 

Standard  deviation 

54.666 

.581 

.623 

T  statistic 

1.26 

13.21 

4.32 

r2 

.92 

*   significant  at  <_  .05 


-32- 


TABLE  VI 

Kodal     (4) 
Plot  Jtaolduals  7S.   SatXaAtmA  ? 


Petroieur 


,  Brisfol    Myers 


l?72 


Qsady* 


till 
;oo  Lcog 


I         t         I         I         I 


I         I         J         I         I         I 


l*)0  woo  nV>  3MO  330d  *0OO  4300 


t 

Pefroitfum 


200«t 

isool 

1000 1 

SO»E 

01 

T 

♦    T 
f»    f 

»      f 

1 

Xn3^rt*rf»enfa 


T         f 


I'?  73 


303  1000 


CacfAv^ 


f 

Onto** 
Corbxle 


£  I  1 


1,300  ^000  1300  iflOO  K30  4000  4300  30OO 


% 
•^ 

^ 


Pafroleum 


i?7¥i 


6i\  r  o  (^ 

Car  b«d« 


JT  *  1  :  Ko  ^c-'^j  3;co  »■»■>* 


Year 


-33- 


TABLL  VII 


Estimates  From  Model '  (4) 
Reduced  40-Finr.  Sample 


1972 


1973 


1974 


19.160 

15.671* 

.986* 

standard  deviation 

24.179 

.878 

.451 

T  statistic 

.79 

17.83 

2.19 

.  r2 

.93 

-17.370 

12.536* 

2.381* 

standard  deviation 

33.477 

1.088 

.  1.026 

■ T  statistic 

.52 

11.52 

2.32 

r2 

.91 

-22.654 

7.807* 

3.437* 

standard  deviation 

29.228 

.677 

.581 

T  statistic 

.78 

11.53 

5.91 

r2 

.93 

*   significant  at  <    .05 


-34- 


TABLE  VIII 


Estimates  From  Model  {5) 
CoirJjined  52-Firm  Sample 
Dependent  Variable:       (x'^/V-tD) 


Coefficients  of 


Constant  Size  Growth  Reciprocal 

Year  a'-=p  '^'o"  ~^o''       ^'2^  "^2*^       °^  Constemt 


*      significant  at  <    .05 


1972  .049*  1.006*  .045  20.408 

std.    dev.  .004  .339  .033 

T  Stat.  12.36  2.97  1.35 
R^                                  .169 


1973                                            .069*            1.105*  -   .003  14.493 

std.    dev.                  .008                  .435  .075 

T  Stat.  9.09                 2.54  -   .04 

R^  . 117  .       .  •  .. 


1974                                              .088*  .749  .046         .      11.363 

std.    dev.                  .010  .484  .076 

T  Stat.  8.73  1.55  .60 
r2                                   .049 


\ 


-35- 


TABLS   IX 


Estimates  From  Model    (6) 
Combined  52-Fim  Sair^ile 


Year 


1972 

standard  deviation 
T  statistic 


^0 

^1 

^2 

306 

11.693* 

1.285 

247 

3.966 

.942 

24 

2.95 

1.36 

r2 

.188 

1973 

.244 

8.836* 

1.609 

' standard  deviation 

.228 

3.245 

1.041 

T  statistic 
R^ 

1.07 

2.72 

1.55 

.179 

1 

1974 

.398* 

4.533* 

1.138 

standard  deviation 

.135 

1.384 

.804 

T  statistic 

2.94 

3.28 

1.42 

r2 

.204 

*  significant  at  <  .05 


-36- 


TAELE   X 


Modal  (5) 
Plot  lUsLdua^j  vs.   Ssdeatad  Y 


/17Z 


\ 


/ 


I  1  1  I  !••  I  (  <  I  I  I  I  I  t  I  ) 

O.'JiU  C.O'.*^  J.usO  O.ia*.  O.ii.-O  0.073  O.^dO  O.iJi)' 


m3 


t         1         1 
Q.oe            O.J/ 

1         1         1 

O.lO 

1         1         1 
0.11            o.i: 

■•- 

\'=]l'i 

-36- 


TAELE   A 


Wximl  (5) 


1111 


C.J*.:,  O,«i0  O.ia* 


)         I  I  I         )         ) 


t  I  I  I  I  r 

O. 13  0.11  0,  IZ 


[mT 


-27 


TABLE   XI 


»iod*l    (6) 
Plot  RaalduaLs  vm,    gsf  Irjitad  Y 


Teta^ 


/f72  I 


>■  • . 

O.JI  . 


A  -  •  - 


tC  .•• 


'  ♦ 


ms 


_Inst rumen  Is 


I  I  r  I  t 

i.o  1.:  t.' 


«   Tr«o3    .rii'.lriunriit'^        '      '    '    ' 


■  y'S?.. 


•  %  .•*'-lS».i 


/?7^ 


6rl^fol    My»rC' 


frlf.-t^on 


)l    .<     f'ofle, 


GlolK" 


5. J 


-38- 


TABLE  XII 


Test  for  Difference  in  Mean  Residuals 
Model  (A)  -  52  Finos 


Source 

Suia 

of 

of 

Variation 

Squares 

Time 

cO 

Capital  Structure 

910,586.6 

Interaction 

41,304.1 

Error 

2,680,720.5 

D.F. 

2 

1 

2 

150 


Mean 
Square 

.0 

910,586.6 

20,652.1 

178,714.7 


h: 


iC 


F*  2,150 
F*  1,150 
F*  2,150 


Probability  of  F* 
0         .9999 


5.095 
.116 


.0241** 
.8909 


Mean  Residuals 


Simple   76.403 
Complex  -76.399 


Test  for  Difference  in  Mean  Residuals 
Model  (4)  -  40  Firms 


Source 
of 
Variation 

Time 

Capital  Striicture 

Interaction 

Error 


Sum 

of 
Squares 

.0 

113,114.2 

2,853.6 

1,525,467.2 


D.F. 

2 

1 

2 

114 


Mean 
Square 

.0 

113,114.2 

1,426.8 

13,381.3 


H' 


H 


H" 


F*  2,114 

F*  1,114 
F*  2,114 


Probability  of  F* 
0         .9999 


8.453 
.107 


.0045** 
.8987 


Mean  Residuals 


Simple   30.702 
Complex  -30.702 


**  Significant  at  £  .05 


Ul. 


-39- 


TABLE  XIII 


Test  for  Difference  in  Mean  Residuals 
Model  (5)  -  52  Firms 


Source 
of 
Variation 

Sum 
of 

Squares 

D.F. 

• 

Mean 
Sqiiare 

Time 

Capital  Structure 

Interaction 

Error 

.0006 
.0063 
.0010 
.1508 

2 

1 

2 

150 

»0003 . 
.0063 
.0005 
.0010 

'■.■•- 

■ 

Probability  of  F* 

Mean  Residtials 

* 

-t 

F*  2,150 

.7210 

.  ■•  ■  •-■ 

-\ 

F*  1,150  - 

6.3 

.0128** 

Simple 
Complex 

-.007 
.005 

Hi 

F*  2,150 

.6253 

Test  for  Difference  in  Mean  Residuals 
Model  (6)  -  52  Firms 


Source 
of 
Variation 

Tine 

Capital  Structure 

Interaction 

Error 


■4 

1 
2 

1 


H 


h: 


Sum 
of 
Squares 

.0 

1.705 

.116 

23.308 


F*  2,150 
F*  1,150 
F*  2,150 


D.F. 

2 

1 

2 

150 


Mean 
Square 

.0 

1.705 
,058 
.155 


Probability  of  F* 
.9999 


10.0 


.0013** 
.6936 


Mean  Residuals 


Simple   .105 
Complex  -.105 


**  Significant  at  <.  .05 
***  Yield  formulation 


-40- 


TSBLE  xrv 

Convertible  Debt 

Bcok     Market    Conversion 
Value*   Value*.   Price 


Common 
Price 


Conversion 

Value* 


Greyhound 

6  1/2 's   ld90  ■ 

Nat' 1  Distillers 
4  1/2 's   1992 

Fibreboard 

4  3/4 's  .  i993 

••;' '  'V !,-.  i... 

Stauffer  Chemical 
4    1/2 's      1991 

Witco  Chemical 
4    1/2 's      1993 


Lone  Star 

5   1/8 's 

1993 

Medusa 

5   3/4 's 

1998 

Crane  Co. 

5's 

1993 

5's 

1994 

Otis  Elevator 

5    1/2' s 

1995 

Fruehauf 

5   1/2' s 

1994 

Amfac,.-.-.  >••, 

".  '•  -1 '  • 

■5's   '■'"■■ 

1989 

5   1/4's 

1994 

$68.1  $68.6  $18,375  $17  $^3.0 


$60.1  $45.2  $25.02 


$19.7 

$14.6 

$31.25 

$35.2 

$32.4 

$53,50 

$15.0 

$14.0 

:•         '^ '  '     ' 

$50.00 

.  ...I    -^ 

$28.7 

$28.4 

$26.00 

$   4.9      -    $   4.9  $35.00 


$18.1  $16.8  $25.00 

$34.8  $32.3  $28.75 


$50.0  $52.5  $46.50 


$60.0  $49.9  $46.25 


$15.75  $37.8,-:::vi 


i  ■- 


$17,375        $11.0 : 


$44,125        $29.0 


$22.75  $  6.8 


$20,875        $23.0 


$33.50  $  4.7 


$15.1 
$35.0 


$13.1 
$30.5 


$35.7143 
$43.67 


$20.50 

$14.8 

$20.50 

$24.tf 

$42.50 

•fj';/'.-.,  ■ 

$45.7 

■    ■*■. 

;::J:;   Ii: 'i 

$31.25 

•   $4Qi.-5 

$26,625 

$11.3 

$26,625 

$21.3 

*     Millions  of  dollars 


■r^.i . 


-41- 


TABLE   3C7 

Convertible   Preferred  Stock 
(Millions  of  dollars) 
Total   Market 


Conversion  Veilue 


Amax       $1  preferred 

Cluett   Peabody        $1  preferred 

Wayne  Gossard 

Monsanto 

Stauffer  Chemical        $1.80  preferred 

Witco  Chemical       $2.65  preferred 

Interpace        5%  preferred 

Lone  Star        $14.50  preferred 

Armco  Steel        $2.10  preferred 

Cooper  Ind.        $5  preferred 

$2.50  preferred 

Scovill 

Eaton 

Amfac        $1.00  B  preferred 
GAF        $1.20  preferred 
GATX       $2.50  preferred 


$    73.2 

$ 

58.9 

$    21.8 

$ 

14.2 

$      7.3 

$ 

7.0 

, 

$  140 . 2 

$128.1 

:  •-*'    '  ■■  '-.  \ 

$    17.2 

$ 

17.3 

■'  ■  -. 

$    15.6 

$ 

15.5 

:^:V-K.r    -•; 

$    23-3 

$ 

15.7 

J.- ..  •"  ,w 

$    13.6 

$ 

12.0 

—•"■■■-  ■' ■  ■  • 

$123.6 

$ 

79-5 

$    16.8 
$    27.7 

$ 
$ 

14.6 
^2.2 

■;  • .    ."'■■  i: 

$   59.2 

$ 

60.1 

\-  ■■  -  • 

$30.1 

$30.5 

•> 

.     $    17.7 

$ 

14.7 

.  .'  ■":  r     -  : 

$    74.1 

$ 

69.4 

'.'  *'     -,  '•:      ■ 

$   38.7 

$36.9 

-42- 
Footnotes 

1.  For  example,  see  Kanada  (12,  13),  Stiglitz  (27),  Rubinstein  (24),  Merton  (17), 
and  tliller  (18). 

2.  For  instance,  see  Boness  and  Frankfurter  (4). 

3.  MM  explain  in  both  (19,  fnt.  37)  and  in  (21,  p.  357)  that  this  issue  was 
avoided  in  their  empirical  tests  since  they  had  few  convertible  issues  in 
their  samples. 

4.  Soldofsky  (26)  estimated  $12.4  billion  of  convertible  bonds  and  $17,8 
billion  of  convertible  preferred  stock  was  outstanding  in  1969.   From  1970 
to  1977  new  issues  of  convertible  bonds  ranged  from  a  high  of  $3.7  billion 
in  1971  to  a  low  of  $.5  billion  in  1974.   New  issues  of  nonconvertible  bonds 
ranged  from  a  low  of  $20.1  billion  in  1973  to  a  high  of  $40.4  billion  in  1975. 
New  issues  of  preferred  and  common  stock  ranged  from  lows  of  $1.4  billion 

and  $4.0  billion  in  1970  and  1974  respectively  and  highs  of  $3-7  billion  and 
$10.7  billion  in  1971  and  1972  respectively.   Standard  and  Poor's  Trade  and 
Securities,  Statistics,  Banking  and  Finance,  July,  1978,  p.  27. 

5.  For  a  good  discussion  of  the  concept,  see  Hubbard  (14). 

6.  Following  Fama  and  Miller  (9,  Chp.  4),  a  frictionless  market  is  assumed  in 
terms  of  infinitely  divisible  securities,  costless  information,  the  absence  of 
transaction  costs  and  taxes.   Further,  all  financial  arrangements  are  equally 
available  to  individuals  and  firms;  individuals  and  firms  are  price  takers. 
Finally,  investors  are  assumed  to  protect  themselves  from  dilution  (expro- 
priation without  compensation)  by  means  of  subordination  rules,  pre-emptive 
issues,  and  other  "me  first"  rules. 

7.  This  tradeoff  is  explained  by  Onsi  and  Frankfurter  (22)  who  also  develop  a 

new  method  of  calculating  earnings  per  share  based  on  the  opportunity  loss     ' 
concept. 

8.  This  point  is  discussed  using  the  states  of  the  world  model  in  (9,  pp.  178-181). 

9.  See  Poensgen  (23,  pp.  91-94)  for  these  empirical  results. 

10.  Modigliani  and  Idler  (19,  p.  291)  and  Soldofsky  (26,  p.  61)  offer  this 
explanation. 

11.  The  tax,  savings  from  interest  on  convertible  debt  \-rLll   be  lower  than  that  from 
interest  on  straight  debt. 

12.  An  example  of  a  direct  test  is  that  of  Boness  and  Frankfurter  (4),  where  the 
vector  of  disturbances  for  each  firm  is  tested  for  homogeneity. 

13.  The  market  risk  measures  are  explained  below.   The  nineteen  accounting  variables 
listed  in  Appendix  2  were  used.   Both  raw  scores  and  factor  scores  were  examined. 
Further  details  concerning  the  clustering  procedures  can  be  found  in  (10). 


14.  On  average,  the  515  firms  are  more  risky  than  firms  included  In  the  Standard 
and  Poor's  index,  as  evidenced  by  an  average  beta  of  1.194,  but  the  average 
monthly  return  is  also  higher  than  the  index.   In  regard  to  leverage,  the  most 
prevalent  feature  is  the  importance  of  current  liabilities  as  a  contributor  to 
total  debt,  a  fact  noted  by  MM  in  (21) . 

15.  The  model  used  is  of  the  form: 

Zj  =  ajiFi  4-  aj2F2  +  .  .  .  +  ajm^m  +  djVj  (j  =  1,  2,  .  .  .  ,  n) 

where  each  of  the  n  variables  is  described  linearly  in  terms  of  m  common  factors 
and  a  unique  factor.   See  Harman  (31,  p.  15). 

16.  Test  for  differences  in  means  were  done  using  the  ANOVA  model  at  the  1% 
significance  level. 

17.  However,  if  convertible  securities  are  excluded  from  debt,  the  difference  is 
not  significant.  .- .  -  •  * 

18.  Test  dates  are  subsequently  referred  to  as  1972,  1973,  and  1974.   The  52-firm 
sample  had  no  major  capital  structure  changes  during  January  for  the  three- 
year  test  period. 

19.  Sources  of  price  data  included: 

Moody's  Bond  Record,  Moody's  Investors  Service,  Inc. 
Bond  Guide,  Standard  and  Poor's  Corporation 
"       Stock  Guide,  Standard  and  Poor's  Corporation 
Barron's,  Dow  Jones  and  Company,  and 
Daily  Stock  Price  Record,  Standard  and  Poor's  Corporation 

Financial  s'tatement  data  was  obtained  from: 

Microfiche,  by  Disclosure,  Inc. 

Moody's  Industrial  Manual,  Moody's  Investors  Services,  Inc. 

Moody's  Transportation  Manual,  Moody's  Investors  Services,  Inc.,  and      ' 

CO>£PUSTAT. 

20.  This  was  true  for  several  reasons.   First,  current  liabilities  comprise  a  sub- 
stantial portion  of  total  firm  debt.   Second,  about  one-half  of  all  debt  issues 
are  privately  placed  and  are  not  traded  in  the  market.   Third,  the  market 
prices  of  most  debt  issues  did  not  deviate  greatly  from  par  during  the  test 
period. 

21.  A  summary  of  the  calculations  is  provided  in  (10),  Exhibit  4-26. 

22.  Of  the  independence,  normality  and  constant  variance  assumptions,  the  most 
important. is  independence.   Given  this  design  it  is  known  that  the  test  for 
differences  in  means  is  relatively  robust  to  departures  from  normality  and 
equal  variance  assumptions  (25).   In  regard  to  independence,  as  possible  con- 
cern is  that  residuals  for  the  same  firm  observed  at  three  points  in  time  are 
correlated.   To  the  extent  this  is  true,  the  two-way  design  has  the  effect  of 
artifically  increasing  the  sample  and  the  probability  of  Type-I  error.   Vfhlle 
a  more  elegant  design  could  be  used  to  exploit  any  expected  correlations,  in- 
stead, simple  one-way  analyses  for  individual  years  will  be  used  to  supplement 
the  two-way  analysis.   If  inconsistencies  result,  alternate  designs  can  be 
explored. 


-44- 

23.  Residual  plots  for  the  reduced  sample  showed  a  reduction  in  the  severity  of 
both  the  heteroscedasticity  and  outlier  problems.   Only  two  possible  outliers 
remained,  Pullman  (+3  s.d.)  in  1972  and  Amfac  (-3.5  s.d.)  in  1974. 

24.  The  absence  of  interactions  implies  that  the  main  effects  are  meaningful 
measures  of  the  differences  between  groups. 

25.  One-way  analyses  were  also  run  on  residuals  from  model  (4).   For  the  52-firm 
sample,  capital  structure  was  significant  at  5%  to  15%  levels  in  the  three 
years.   For  the  40-firm  sample,  significance  level  were  from  .5%  to  5%.   This 
provides  evidence  that  the  results  of  the  two-way  analysis  are  not  greatly 
influenced  by  any  correlations  among  a  specific  firm's  residuals  over  time. 

26.  Miller  (18)  has  suggested  that  the  previously  assumed  tax  savings'" from  debt 
may  be  substantially  overstated.   This  should  not  affect  the  results  of  the 
present  study  as  long  as  there  is  no  differential  bias  in  the  calculations  for 
the  simple  versus  complex  groups. 

27.  The  anomalies  were  significant  bo  differences  for  1973  and  1974,  and  a  dif- 
ference in  b-,  that  was  significant  at  the  9.3  percent  level  for  1973. 


-45- 


Appendlx  1. 


Arbltraga  iqi  the  Two  Period  Risk  Claas  Model 
Complez  Capital  Structtire  Case 


In  the  two  period  tnodel,*  the  flrti  makes  production  declaions  at 
period  -  1  that  will  yield  probability  distributions  of  net  cash  eam«>  . 
Ings  at  period  -  2  to  be  paid  to  security  holders  at  that  tine*  'The 
role  of  the  capital  market  is  to  establish  prices  for  such  securities 
at  period  -  1.  Let  us  consider  the  icarket  values  of  three  f IrmB— one 
unlevered,  a  second  with  straight  debt  as  part  of  its  ca|>lt«X.  struer'>: 
turef  and  a  third  whose  debt  can  be  converted  into  a  specif  1«1  percent-;- 
age  y  of  the  number  of  coomon  shares  Issued  at.  period  -  1  at . the  option 
of  the  holder  at  period  -  2.  It  is  presisaed  that  the  market  at 
period  -  1  anticipates. the  sans  period  -  2  net  cash  earnings  for  the  "^"' 

three  firms  such  that  X  ^^v  "  ^f?-)  "  ^  f2")  "  ^(.T\*   *^®^®  '^®  subscripts 
mean  complex,  levered  and  tmlevered  respectively.  In  the  ensuing  dls- 
cusslon,  the  following  notation  is  used,  with  subscripts  as  above:  '- 

'i-rV  ■  total  niarket  value  of  the  firm  at  period  -  1«  -■  ■.^■;'-  ;'.i-;''-^'/  ^ 
S  ■•  total  market  value  of  coaaaon  shares  at  period  -  1,    /^;!  . 
B  -  total  market  value  of  debt  at  period  -  1.     .  _   -/.■■■ 
""•:.' f-'-'R  "total  pajraentes  to  debtholders  at  period  -  2.\   •:.l,;,,;.'j.^^.a 

Let  us  now  consider  the  market  value  of  a  percent  investments  in  eacb-y-;, 

.firm.   .•■•.. 

The  market  value  of  an  a  percent  investment  in  the  unlevered  firm 


«Vi)""'u(i)  -::-m 


•;^ 


<  - 


i^i: 


!^^... 


'.■■^■i  <i/-.;:0- 


'  '*The  example  asstuoea  a  perfect  market  (see  footnote  6.)  and  no 
taxes.  Notation  follows  Fana  and  Miller  [9,  Chp.  A] .    -     .  .,  '  '  --  ' 


-46- 


asd  the  period  -  2  return  Is: 

^  «\(2)  "«^2)  <9> 

■''■'''"■    ■    "  •'-■;  ■■  •  -  ■'"  u 

An  Investor  could  obtain  the  same  return  by  purchasing  a  percent  of 

.      ■   ,  r  *,  ?-.. 

the  stocks  and  bonds  of  the  levered  fins.  In  this  case,  ignoring  taxes,' 

■  -^  S'.i:zy;,i/   ;iv,  nj; 

the  market  value  of  the  Investment  would  be 


v-^.U/- 


»•-  Sj 


and  the  period  -  2  return  would  be 

^''"'-  «fX(2)  "  \(2)3  -^  °^(2)  -  «  ^(2)    '  ->  ^^  -  --^^  -.XU).  ,^ 

■  -  ■  .  ', ,     .- ,   J. . 

Similarly,  an  investor  in  the  complex  firm  could  obtain  the  same  return 

''■*''■  ■      '   „  .  -  s.  - ... 

by  purchasing  a  percent  of  that  firm's  stock  and  convertible  bonds,  and 
the  period  -  2  return  will  not  depend  on  conversion.*  The  market  value 


of  this  investment  would  be 

■"'""■   '"   "  ■    ■■   '*  ■"  '■  ""' "  ""  '   ^i  ::::',:.     ..ire 


^■-     -     -■■-     ■'■    ■■-"■'    v-Wl,'   .;:  ,-ri;:J.-  >••-::':-;;....•  -^\  ^.{-   ^n^s^.. 


If  conversion  does  not  occur,  the  period  -  2  return  will  be  computed  as 
in  Cll)  above  and  would  be      -'■■   j./      ■  ^;v  .  -\  -  -.;  ::r\.-^  ,vnij  ???•;  ^'r  -i 


^n  .  ,«I^2  -  \(2)^  -^  "  \C2)  --  °  ^(2)   .   ,  .  .   ^  ,  .^  ^  ^^^  .  ,  ^"^ 
If  conversion  does  occur,  the  investor  will  receive 


*Conversion  will  occur,  if,  after  equilibrium  prices  are  established, 
the  price  associated  with  the  "option"  portion  of  the  security  is  such 
that  the  expected  return  from  holding  the  "right"  in  the  original  form, 
rather  than  common  stock  form,  vanishes.  :,: 


-47- 


•  V  .°iX(2)  -  y  ^(2)^  +  "  y  ^C2)  "  °  ^(2)  ^^*> 

The  two  components  of  the  left  side  of  (14)  refer  to  the  return  appli-:  r 

cable  to  the  old  shares  plus  the  return  applicable  to  shares  received  . : . 

from  conversion.  .'  ":'  iL.l.t  j^ 

Kov  consider  investor  actions  if  the  market  value  of  the  unlevered 

firm  is  higher  than  the  other  firms  such  that  V  >  V.  "  V  .  In  this  -vt; 

u    D    c 

case,  it  is  clear  that  no  investor  would  want  to  hold  shares  in  the  tin- 
levered  firm  because  the  same  return  could  be  obtained  at  less  cost  hy:.  ». 
purchasing  a  combination  of  debt  and  shares  in  either  of  the  other  firms. 
Thus,  arbitrage  opportunities  would  prevent  the  unlevered  fixna  f r on- ;:. ,>;.>!' 
selling  at  a  higher  price  than  the  other  firms.  \^,.:i  -  »^  Vl  ; 
The  siore  important  arbitrage  arguments  have  centered  around  actions 

of  o  S.  shareholders  in  the  levered  firm  where  V,  >  V  .  The  share-   ;„'i 
b  b    u 

holder's  period  -  2  return  will  be  -.;  a  ■■   .ra?  j;.;.v.i 

°t^2)-\(2)^  .  i^^^ 

■     •   ■  •■  -■   ..  :  .;-.  :  ,->,  -.oirj 

In  this  case,  the  shareholder  owning  a  S,  has  the  opportunity  to  tin- 
do  the  leverage  by  selling  his  shares  and  purchasing  a  shares  in  the 
unlevered  firm.  The  purchase  would  be  made  with  funds  obtained  from 
the  sale  of  the  levered  shares  and  personal  borrowing.  Since  the  capi- 
tal market  is  perfect,  the  Investor  must  be  able  to  borrow  a   B,  ,,v  on 
personal  account,  by  promising  to  pay  lenders  o  times  the  levered 
firm's  bond  payments  at  period  -  2.  The  period  -  2  return  will  be 
^^"^(2^  ~  ^(2^^*   ^^®  same  as  (15)  above.  But  since  V,  >  V  ,  the  return 
from  a  V  can  be  obtained  at  less  cost,  and  no  investor  would  choose 
to  own  S,  . 

D 


-A8- 


Now  consider  the  case  of  V  >  V,  >  V  for  an  a  S  shareholder  In 

c    b    u         c 

the  complex  firm.  A  variety  of  options  to  achieve  the  same  return  at  a 

lover  cost  are  available  to  this  Investor;  we  will  consider  Just  one 

at  this  time.  ....;; 

.V  One  possible  action  for  th^  complex  firm's  shareholder  would  be  to 

sell  his  a  S  o-,7nershlp  and  buy  a  S  ^  »=  a  V  o^marshlp  in  the  unlevered  , 

firm,  financing  part  of  the  purchase  vith  personal  borrowing.  Again, 

since  markets  are  perfect,  the  inv>istor  must  be  able  to  borrow  a  B  ,^k      ,. 

on<piersonal  account,  promising  to  rep^y  a  R  .„•,  or  o  y  X^„v  at  period  7-. 2, 

depending  on  conr/srsion.  The  net  period  -  1  cost  to  the  investor  is 

<»[V  /,x  ~  B  ,,v),  and  his  return  on  V  will  be  afX,_.  -  R  ,_.]  or   .... 
"■  uCl)    c(l)  '  u         '  (2)    c(2)''    .-jx-.ti  : 

o[X^_i::^-  y'X>.2\]»  depending  on  coni'ersion.  This  is  the  same  return 
that  would  be  achieved  by  holding  a  S  ,.,..  But  since  V  <  V  ..this  re- . 
turn  can  be  achieved  at  a  lower  cost  by  investing  in  V  .  Thus,  the  In- 

U  ":  i 

dependence  of  capital  structure  and  value  continues  to  hold  for  the  com- 
plex  capital  structure  case.  Vs-'^ 


•*n'i* ' i"*,'}   y V c*; ".'"' '  c*7'"c  h''i^    v" 


,vii.=5^  ^.tdi  .^;I 


an:;  -fi.  s:::.cvla  -:  ^.;^.ecf!.-i"i  ;i:.f  tv;^.!;  •".■... ^  y-:   ^  :'r-^vvii  ^^j  ..!> 


■?■  .-i 


-A9- 


Appendix  2« 


Accounting  Risk  Measures  Used  in  Clustering  Routines 


Satloa 


Ccilculation* 


1.  Dividend  payout  Z  DATA  (21,  I)  /  E  DATA  (20,  I) 

2.  Capital  expenditures/Total  Assets  Z   DATA  (30,  1)   /  I  DATA  (6,  I) 

3.  Capital  fexpenditures/Net  Income  I  DATA  (30,  I)  /  Z  DATA  (18,  I) 

4.  Average  asset  turnover 


5.  Average  profit  margin 

6.  Senior  d^t/Tot2d  Assets 

7.  Long  term  debt/Conanon  Equity 

8.  Retiirh  on  Common  Equity 

9.  Return  on  Invested  Capital 

10.  Current  Ratio 


Z  DATA  (12,  I)  /  E  DATA  (6,  I)    „;■- 

Z  DATA  (18,  I)  /  Z  DATA  (12,  1) 

Z  (DATA  (9,  I)  +  DATA  (10,  I))  /  Z  DATA  (6,  I) 

Z  DATA  (9,  I)  /  Z  DATA  (11,  I) 

Z  DATA  (20,  1)  /  Z  DATA  (11,  I) 

Z  (DATA  (18,  I)  +  DATA  (15,  I))  / 

Z  (DATA  (9,  I)  +  DATA  (10,  1)  -f  DATA  (11,  I))  - 

Z  DATA  (4,  I)  /  Z  DATA  (5,  I)  .    ' 


ferbwth  Rates** 

11.  Total  Assets 

12.  Operating  Earnings 

13.  Met  Income 

14*  Earnings  Per  Share  (Primary) 

15.  Operating  Earnings  Per  Share 

16.  Capital  Expenditxires 

17.  Retvurn  on  Comnion  Equity 

18.  Retxim  on  Invested  Capital 

19.  Dividends  Per  Share 


Variable  Numbers 


6 

13  - 

14 

18 

« 

58 

13  - 

14  /  25 

30 

20  / 

11 

18  + 

15  /  9  ■»■ 

10 

+ 

11 

26 

*  Nvcabers  refer  to  COMPUSTAT  variable  numbers 
**  Geometric  growth  rates  were  calculated  as  follows: 

.   -  n  -^ 


gmg  »  emtilog    Z  log  (1  +  g^) 
=  t=>l 


-  1 


n 


-50- 


REFEPvSNCES 

1.  Barges,  Alexander.   The  Effect  of  Capital  Structure  on  the  Cost  of  Capital, 
Prentice-Hall,  1963. 

2.  Ben-Zion  Uri  and  Sal  S.  Shalit .   "Size  and  Other  Determinants  of  Equity 
Risk,"  Journal  of  Finance,  September,  1975,  pp.  1015-1026. 

3.  Black,  Fischer  andMyron  Schol^.s.   "The  Pricing  of  Options  and  Corporate 
Liabilities,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy,  May-June  1973,  pp.  637-654.  -  ..'. 

4.  Boness,  James  A.  and  George  !I-  Frankfurter.  "Evidende  of  Non-Homogeneity   ■; 
of  Capital  Costs  Within  'Risk  Classes',"  Journal  of  Finance,  June  1977, 

pp.  775-788.  •-:■  ;  _ .;,  .'....r;  vA  ,i. 

5.  Chen,  Andrew  "fl.  Y:.'"A  Model  6f  Warrant  Pricing  in  a  DjTiamic  Market,"  .-.v'   5 
Journal  of  Finance,  December  1970. 

^-.T-j;-.^  /.' ■"••;^ '•-!.' ;:■  "oi:/;-^.-,  .^ 

6.  Elton,  Edwin  J.  and  Martin  J.  Gruber.   "Homogeneous  Groups  and  the 
Testing  of  Economic  kypotheses,"  JFQA,  January  1970,  __pp.  581-602..  i.;<.f  tko^A  .*. 

7.  ♦   "Improved  Forecasting  Through  the  Design  of  Homogeneous  Groups," 

Tlie  Journal  of  Business,  1973,  pp^i  432-450. 

8.  Everitt,  Brian.   Cluster  Analysis,  Heinemann  Educational  Books,  1974. 

9.  Fama,  Eugene,  F.  and  Merton  H.  Miller.   The  Theory  of  Finance,  Dryden  :  ■:<  .ci 
Press,  1972. 

10.  Frecka,  Thomas  J.  "Tlie  Effects  of  Complex  Capital  Structures  on  the  Market 
Value  of  Firms,"  Unpublished  dissertation,  Syracuse  University,  1978.' 

11.  Gonedesj  Nicholas  J.   "Evidence  on  the  Information  Content  of  Accounting 
Numbers;   Accounting-Based  and  Clarke t-Based  Estimates  of  Systematic  Ris,"  ..;'- 
JFQA,  June  1973,  pp.  407-444. 

12.  .  Hamada,  R.  S.   "Portfolio  Analysis,  Market  Equilibrium  and  Corporation 

Finance,"  Journal  of  Finance,  March  1969,  pp.  13-31.    .(-:.;■".  r.  l  r;'::'^'Jjr'jiSX:i   .i.f 

13.  .   "The  Effect  of  the  Firm's  Capital  Stiructure  on  the  Systematic. 

Risk  of  Common  Stocks,"  Journal  of  Finance,  May  1972,  pp.  435-452. 

14.  Hubbard,  Philip  M.   "The  M^ny  Aspects  of  Dilution,"  Financial  Analysts* 
Journal,  May-June  1S63,  pp.  33-40.  '■:.-•  ..".o-;;-a;.;  .\.<. 

15.  Johnson,  Robert  W.   Financial  Management,  Fourth  Edition,  Allyn  and  Bacon,... 
1971. 

16.  Logue,  Dennis  E.  and  Larry  J.  Merville,  "Financial  Policy  and  Market 
Expectations,"  Financial  Management ,  Summer,  1972. 


-51- 

17.  Herton,  Robert  C.  "On  the  Pricing  of  Corporate  Debt:  The  Risk  Structure 
of  Interest  Rates,"  Journal  of  Finance,  May  1974,  pp.  449-470. 

18.  Miller,  Merton,   "Debt  and  Taxes,"  Journal  of  Finance,  May  1977,  pp.  261- 
277. 

19.  Modigllani,  Franco  and  Merton  H.  Miller.  "The  Cost  of  Capital,  Corporation 
Finance,  and  the  Theory  of  Investment,"  The  American  Economic  Review, 

June  1958,  pp.  261-297. 

20. _.  "Corporate  Income  Taxes  and  the  Cost  of  Capital:  A  Correction," 

The  American  Economic  Review,  June  1963,  pp.  433-43, 

21.  .  "Some  Estimates  of  the  Cost  of  Capital  to  the  Electric 

Utility  Industry,  1954-57,"  American  Economic  Review,  June  1966,  pp.  334-391. 

i22.  Onsi,  Mohamad  and  G.  M.  Frankfurter.  "An  Opportunity  Loss  Approach  for 

Calculating  Earnings  Per  Share,"  Syracuse  University  School  of  Management, 
Faculty  Research  Working  Paper  Series,  1974. 

23.  Poensgen,  0.  M.   "The  Valuation  of  Convertible  Bonds,"  Industrial  Management 
Review,  Fall  1965  and  Spring  1966,  pp.  77-92  and  83-98. 

24.  Rubinstein,  Mark  E.   "A  Mean-Variance  Synthesis  of  Corporate  Financial 
Theory,"  Journal  of  Finance,  May  1974,  pp.  439-447. 

25.  Scheffe,  Henry.   The  Analysis  of  Variance,  New  York:   John  Wiley  &  Sons, 
1959. 

26.  Soldofsky,  Robert  M.   "Yield-Risk  Performance  on  Convertible  Securities," 
Financial  Analysts'  Journal,  ISIarch-April  1971,  pp.  61065,  79. 

27.  Stiglitz,  J.  E.  "A  Re- examination  of  the  Modigliani-Miller  Theorem," 
American  Economic  Review,  December  1969,  pp.  784-793. 

28.  Turnbull,  Stuart  M.   "Market  Value  and  Systematic  Risk,"  Journal  of  Finance; 
September  1977,  pp.  1125-41. 

29.  ••  Veldnan,  Donald  J.   Fortran  Programming  For  the  Behavioral  Sciences,  ■: 

New  York:  Holt,  Rinehart  and  Winston,  1967.  . 

30.  Wlppern,  R.  F.   "A  Note  on  the  Equivalent  Risk  Class  Assumption,"  The 
Engineering  Economist,  Spring  1966,  pp.  13-22. 

31.  Rarman,  Harry  H.   Modem  Factor  Analysis,  Second  Edition,  Chicago: 
The  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1967. 

32.  Albrecht,  Steve,  Larry  Lookabill,  and  James  McKeown.   "The  Time-Series 
Properties  of  Annual  Accounting  Earnings,"  Journal  of  Accounting  Pvssearch, 
Autumn,  1977,  pp.  226-244. 

33.  Watts,  Ross  and  Richard  Leftwich.   "The  Time  Series  of  Annual  Accounting 
Earnings,"  Journal  of  Accounting  Research,  Autumn,  1977,  pp.  253-271. 


nOUNDf 


t\^. 


3-9-'' ,