Skip to main content

Full text of "The effects of transaction costs and different borrowing and lending rates on the option pricing model"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  LIBRARY 

AT  URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


X^i' 


NOTICE:  Return  or  ranew  all  Ubrary  MaMrtatsI  The  Minimum  Fee  lor 
each  Lost  Book  Is  $50.00. 

The  person  charging  this  material  is  responsible  for 
its  return  to  the  library  from  which  it  was  withdrawn 
on  or  before  the  Latest  Date  stamped  below. 

Theft,  mutilation,  and  undertining  ol  books  are  reasons  tor  discipli- 
nary action  and  may  result  in  dismissal  from  the  University. 
To  renew  call  Telephone  Center,  333-8400 

UNIVERSITY    OF    ILLINOIS    LIBRARY    AT    URBANA-CHAMPAIGN 


DEC  1  0  1995 


L161— O-1096 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  NO.  874 
College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign 
June  1982 


The  Effects  of  Transaction  Costs  and 

Different  Borrowing  and  Lending  Rates  on  the 

Option  pricing  Model 

John  E.  Gilster,  Assistant  Professor 
Department  of  Finance 

William  Lee 
Bendix  Corporation 


Acknowledgment:   The  authors  would  like  to  thank  the  University 
of  Illinois  Investors  in  Business  Education  and  the  University 
of  Illinois  Research  Board  for  financial  support. 

Special  Thanks  go  to  George  Constantinides  who  was  very  smart  (and 
kind  enough)  to  point  out  a  serious  error  in  an  earlier 
version  of  the  paper.   Pvemaining  errors  are,  of  course,  the 
authors ' . 


Abstract 

This  paper  solves  a  stochastic  differential  equation  to  demonstrate 
that  the  market  imperfections  of  transaction  costs  and  different  borrowing 
and  lending  rates  partially  offset  each  other  to  yield  a  range  of 
equilibrium  prices  for  an  option.   The  Black-Scholes  model  price  is 
shown  to  be  in  the  lower  portion  of,  or  entirely  below,  the  equilibrium 
range.   These  observations  are  used  to  explain  several  of  the  mythical 
anomalies  found  in  the  option  pricing  literature. 

The  paper  also  points  out  that  under  some  conditions  there  may  be 
no  equilibrium  option  price.   Instead  there  may  be  a  bounded  disequilibrium 
within  which  a  single  option  will  offer  a  -risk  free  return  above  the 
Treasury  bill  rate,  while  simultaneously  permitting  borrowing  below  the 
borrowing  rate. 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/effectsoftransac874gils 


I.    Introduction 

The  Black-Scholes  model  requires  an  investor  to  create  a  risk  free 
hedge  by  taking  a  position  in  an  option  and  the  opposite  position  in 
the  underlying  stock.   The  stocks  and  options  are  held  in  proportions 
such  that  any  price  movement  in  the  stock  is  perfectly  offset  by  an 
opposite  movement  in  the  option.   These  proportions  are  readjusted  contin- 
uously throughout  the  life  of  the  hedge.   The  hedge  is  therefore  risk  free 
and  yields  the  risk  free  rate. 

If  the  hedge  consists  of  a  long  position  in  common  stock  and  a  short  posi- 
tion in  options  the  hedge  will  require  a  net  investment  on  which  the  investor 
will  earn  the  risk  free  rate  (an  "investment  hedge").   If  the  hedge  consists 
of  a  long  position  in  an  option  and  a  short  position  in  the  stock,  the  hedge 
supplies  funds  to  the  investor  for  which  he  pays  interest  (a  "borrowing  hedge"). 

The  original  Black-Scholes  (.1972)  option  pricing  model  assumes  zero 
transaction  costs  and  implicitly  assumes  borrowing  and  lending  at  the  risk 
free  rate.  Under  these  assumptions  the  option  price  appropriate  to  an  in- 
vestment hedge  is  equal  to  the  option  price  appropriate  to  a  borrowing 
hedge  and  this  determines  a  unique  equilibrium  option  price.   This  will  be 
shown  to  be  a  special  case  of  a  more  general  model. 

If  transaction  costs  are  ignored,  the  effects  of  different  borrowing 
and  lending  rates  are  relatively  obvious.   The  option  price  appropriate 
to  an  investment  hedge  is  the  traditional  Black  and  Scholes  price  (and 
therefore  earns  the  risk  free  rate)  and  the  option  price  appropriate  to 
a  borrowing  hedge  can  be  calculated  from  the  Black-Scholes  model  equa- 
tion with  the  investor's  borrowing  rate  substituted  for  the  Treasury  bill 
rate  (the  hedge  therefore  costs  the  borrowing  rate).   Obviously,  the 
option  price  appropriate  to  a  borrowing  hedge  will  be  greater  than  the 
option  price  appropriate  to  an  investment  hedge. 


-2- 

When  transaction  costs  are  considered,  option  prices  must  be  adjusted 
so  as  to  earn  the  investor  the  risk  free  rate  on  an  investment  hedge  or 
cost  him  the  borrowing  rate  on  a  borrowing  hedge  net  of  transaction  costs. 

In  essence,  the  profit  from  an  investment  hedge  comes  from  the  de- 
clining time  premium  of  an  option  that  has  been  short  sold  (or  "written"). 
The  additional  revenue  needed  to  pay  transaction  costs  can  be  generated  by 
raising  the  initial  option  price  to  provide  for  a  greater  decline  in  time 
premium  and  a  greater  profit  for  the  hedge's  short  position  in  options. 

In  essence,  the  cost  of  a  borrowing  hedge  results  from  the  deteriorat- 
ing time  premium  of  the  hedge's  long  position  in  options.   To  provide 
for  borrowing  at  the  market  rate  after  transaction  costs  the  initial  op- 
tion price  must  be  reduced  so  as  to  provide  for  less  deterioration  in  time 
premium  and  more  funds  available  to  pay  transaction  costs. 

The  reader  will  note  that  if  transaction  costs  and  the  borrowing  and 
lending  rate  spread  are  of  precisely  the  right  size,  the  transaction  cost 
adjusted  option  price  for  an  investment  hedge  can  equal  the  transaction 
cost  adjusted  option  price  for  a  borrowing  hedge.   In  this  case  the  market 
imperfection  of  different  borrowing  and  lending  rates  and  the  market  imper- 
fection of  positive  transaction  costs  cancel  to  produce  a  unique  equilibrium 
option  price. 

This  precise  cancellation  is,  of  course,  rare.   Usually  one  of  the 
two  imperfections  dominates  yielding  a  bounded  range  of  option  prices. 
Section  IV  and  the  conclusion  of  the  paper  point  out  the  potentially 
bizarre  nature  of  some  of  these  situations. 

Section  I  of  the  paper  presents  an  introduction  and  a  general 
description  of  the  problem.   Section  II  modifies  the  Black-Scholes 


-3- 

option  pricing  model  to  include  rebalancing  transaction  costs.      Section 
III  suggests  ways  in  which  some   investors   may   reduce   the  cost   of  acquir- 
ing and  terminating  the  hedge  position.      Section  IV  calculates  option 
prices  with  transaction  costs  and  different  borrowing  and  lending  rates. 
Section  V  presents   a  conclusion  and  summary. 

II.      Transaction   Costs   of  Hedge   Rebalancing 

The  Black-Scholes  model  assumes  that   the  price  of  an  option,  w(x,t), 
is  a  function  of  stock  price  x,   and  time,   t.      In   this  case,   the  equity 
in  an  investing  hedge  of  one  stock  share  long  and  n  =  1/w     options 
short  is  X  -  wn  (where  the  subscript  refers   to  the  partial  derivative 
of  w(x,t)  with  respect  to  its   first  argument).      The  equity  change   in  a 
short  interval  At  can  be  expressed  as: 

A(x  -  w/w  )   =  Ax  -  A(wn)  (1) 

=   Ax  -    [w(x+Ax,   t+At)n(x+Ax,   t+At)   -  w(x,t)n(x,t)  ] 
which  can  be  expanded  to: 

=   Ax  -   {[w+w  Ax+^^^(Ax)^  +  W2At][n+n^Ax+|n      (Ax)^+w  At]    -  wn} 

Substituting  v^  =   (Ax/x)    /At,   and  keeping  only  the  terms  of 
Ax  and  At ,   equation   (1)   becomes : 


12  2 
A(x-w/w  )   =   (-  -TV  X  w     -w  )nAt  + 


12   2  2   2 

(-Axwn^/At-wn_-  -rv  x  wo,    -v  x  w  n.)At 


(2) 


-4-  I 

The  first  term  on  the  right  side  of  equation  (2)  is  the  part  of 
the  equity  change  which  yields  the  risk-free  rate  as  derived  in  the 
Black  and  Schole  model: 

Ax  -  Aw/w,     =  Ax-  [w(x+Ax,t+At)  -  w(x,t)]/w^ 

1       2 

=  Ax  -  [w+w^Ax+-w^^(Ax)   +  w^At-wJ/w 


1   .  ii<. 


1    2  2 
=  C-^j_j_x  V  At-W2At)/w^ 

=  C-|vVw^^-W2)nAt  -.  ^.;  <^3) 

The  second  term  of  equation  (2)  is  the  extra  capital  required  to 

2 
maintain  the  hedge  position.   The  extra  capital  is  composed  of  the  change 

in  the  number  of  options  An  at  the  changed  price  -w(x+Ax,  t+At)  i.e., 

-wCx+Ax,  t+At) An 

=  -[w+w^Ax+-iw^j_(Ax)2-Kj2At]  [n+n^Ax+in^j_(Ax)2+n2At-n] 

17   9  7   7  •  r 

=  (-Axwn  /At-wn  -  -rv  x  wn  -v  x  w  n  )At  (4) 

Accompanying  the  extra  capital,  the  transaction  cost  by  which 
the  equity  change  should  be  reduced  is  a  |  -  w(x+Ax, t+At)An  |,  where  a  is 
the  transaction  cost  rate  for  options.   Therefore,  the  equity  change  Ax  -  Aw/w 
yields  the  risk-free  investing  rate  r  on  the  equity  x  -  w/w  after  the 
cost,  a  I  -  w(x+Ax, t+At)An  |,  has  been  deducted.   Therefore: 


Ax 


-  Aw/w  -  a|  -  w(x+Ax,t+At)An|   =  (x-w/w^)r^At  (5) 


Substituting  equations  (3)  and  (4)  into  equation  (5)  and  replacing 

2       2  3  2 

n,  n^,  v\.^^   and  n^  by  1/w^,  -  w^^/w^  ,  (2w^^  ""l^lll^/'^l  ^"*^  ~  "l2''^l 

respectively,  yields: 


-5- 


i  i  1   2   2  ,.. 

r  w  -  r  xw     -  -TV  X  w       -  w„   =  ctg  (6) 

where 

19    9  9    9 

g  =  E(w^    I    -   5xwiL./At   -  WTU   -  -rv  X  wil.      -  v  x  w  n^     |) 

0      0  0  0     1 

=   E   I    Axww     /(w  At)   +  WW     /w     +v  X    (-w\>?       /w^  +^^^^/w^+w^^)  |       (7) 

Equation  (6)  is  the  differential  equation  for  the  option  price 
from  an  investing  hedge.   Similarly,  one  could  be  derived  from  a  bor- 
rowing hedge,  i.e., 

b     b      1  2  2  .-v 

r  w  -  r  xw  -  -^  X  w   -  w  =  -ag,  (8) 

where  r  is  the  appropriate  borrowing  rate. 

Equation  (7)  makes  it  clear  that  as  At  ->  0,  g  approaches  infinity, 
yielding  the  horrifying  (though  not  entirely  unexpected)  result  that  with 
continuous  rebalancing,  transaction  costs  will  be  infinite  for  any  posi- 
tive transaction  cost  rate. 

Fortunately,  this  result  is  more  of  a  mathematical  artifact  than  a 
practical  problem.  As  the  tables  presented  in  Section  IV  demonstrate, 
short  finite  interval  rebalancing  (e.g.,  daily)  results  in  very  reason- 
able  transaction  costs.  ' 

To  solve  for  equation  (6),  it  is  reasonable  to  assume  the  solution 
w""-  differs  only  slightly  from  the  Black  and  Scholes  model  solution  because 
the  transaction  cost  rate,  a,  is  quite  small.   Let  w^  be  the  Black  and 
Scholes  solution  and  aw'  the  correction,  then 

vr^  =  w°  +  aw'    (w°  >>  aw')  (9) 


-6-  I 

Replacing  w  by  w-"-  in  equation  (6)  : 

i      i   '   1  2  2  '     ' 
r  w'  -  r  xw  -  -^v  X  w   -  w-  =  g  (10) 

Since  w  =  w  ,  g  can  be  approximated  by 

-     .  w,    -  -. 

T7    1    A     0  0,,  O,^.     ,      00/0^     2   2/     00  2,  02  ^100      ,0^     O.i    „,. 
g  =   E    I    Axw  w^^/(w^At)   +  w  w^,/w^  +  V  X   (-w  w^^   /w^     +  -^w  ^-^n'^l       "n^    '    ^'^■^^ 

Because  the  hedge  will  not  change  when  t  =  t*,  x  ->  °°  or  x  =  0, 
there  will  be  no  transactions  costs.  Therefore,  w  =  w  and 

w'(x,t*)  =  w'(",t)  =  w'(0,t)  =  0  (12) 

The  same  substitution  for  w'   used  in  the  Black  and  Scholes  model 
yields :  ,  .        '  ' 

w'(x,t)   =  e^'"(t*-t)2(u,s)  (13) 


where : 

2  2 

u  =  2_(ri  _  |_)    [to  J  -    (r^  -  f-)    (t-t*)],  (14) 

V  -       . 

2  , 
s  =  -  ^(r^  -  f-r   (t-t*)  (15) 

and  c  is  the  exercise  price  of  the  option. 

Equation  (15)  implies : 

2 
t  =  t*  -  sv^/(2(r^  -  2~^^^ 

.-  •  I,  ■  > 

Equation  (14)  implies: 

2 

X    V 


c  exp  {(u-s)/[r^  -  j")  ]  } 


-7- 

Substituting  x  and  w'  into  equation  (10)  and  (11): 

Z2  -  ^11  =  h  (16) 

with  h  =  h(u,s)  being  the  function  g  after  multiplying  by 

e        V  /(2(r  -  — )  )  and  substituting  in  x  and  t.   The  boundary 

conditions,  equation  (12),  become: 

Z  (u,0)  =  Z  (~,0)  =  Z(-",0)  =  0 

The  solution  for  equation  (16)  is  given  by  Butkov  (1968,  pp.  525- 


526): 


ZCu,s)  = 


|.oo  ^_(u_u')2/4(s-s') 
-   (4Tr(s-s'))-'-^^ 


h  (u',s')  du'ds'  (17) 


Substituting  (17)  into  (13)  and  then  (9),  yields  the  solution  w  . 
Similarly,  w  can  be  solved  for  by  using  interest  rate  r  and  replacing 
equations  (9)  and  (10)  with: 

w  =  w  +  aw'  and  (18) 

r  w'  -  r  X  w  -  -jv^x  w   -  w  =  -g  (19) 

III.   Initiation  and  Termination  Costs 

In  option  hedging,  the  lowest  cost  market  participant  will  usually  be 
the  investor  for  whom  acquiring  (or  short  selling)  the  common  stock  portion 
of  the  hedge  is  a  by-product  of  other  activities. 

An  investment  hedge  consists  of  a  long  position  in  common  stock  and 
a  short  position  in  options.   An  investor  who  owns  but  wishes  to  sell  the 
common  stock  for  which  the  hedge  is  to  be  written  can  form  the  hedge 


-8- 

without  incurring  a  marginal  cost  for  buying  or  selling  the  stock.   In 
this  case,  instead  of  selling  the  stock  immediately  the  stock  is  retained 
and  the  usual  hedged  position  of  w/w  worth  of  options  are  written  for 
each  share  of  stock  held.   This  hedge  is  held  until  either: 

1)  The  option  price  drops  below  1/16  point  at  which  time  C.B.O.E. 
trading  in  the  option  is  halted.   A  hedge  can  no  longer  be 
formed  and  the  coinmon  stock  is  (finally)  sold. 

2)  The  option  is  in  the  money  at  expiration  and  the  stock  is 
called  away.   In  this  case  transaction  costs  are  calculated 
as  if  the  stock  were  sold  at  the  exercize  price,  C  rather 
than  the  actual  stock  price  X*. 

As  soon  as  the  hedge  is  formed,  stock  price  movements  are  neutral- 
ized and  the  stock  used  in  the  hedge  is  in  effect  sold.   The  initial 
cash  flows  (including  the  savings  from  not  actually  selling  the  stock) 
are: 

aw/w,  -  a  X 
1     X 

where  a  is  the  transaction  cost  rate  for  common  stock  transactions. 
When  the  stock  is  finally  (actually)  sold  and  the  hedge  position  closed 
out  the  flows  are: 

a  >an(x^;c)  =  a  (x^-w^)  (20) 

X  X 

where  the  superscript  y  indicates  values  at  the  time  the  hedge  is  closed 
out  (not  necessarily  at  expiration;  see  contingency  1  above). ^ 

In  equilibrium  (ignoring  dividends)  the  discounted  present  value 
of  the  expected  value  of  x^  is  x.   Therefore,  when  the  hedge  is  con- 
structed the  risk  adjusted  present  value  of  the  total  cash  outflows 
are: 


-9- 

aw/w  -  a  e'^^*^E(w^)  (21) 

where  K  is  the  discoimt  rate  appropriate  to  the  option  and  At  is  the 
time  until  the  option  hedge  is  closed  out.   Equation  (21)  shows  that 
the  investor  has,  in  effect,  paid  a(w/w  )  plus  continuous  rebalancing 
costs  to  save  the  transaction  costs  on  the  amount  by  which  x*  might 
exceed  c  at  expiration  (i.e.,  w*) .  Under  reasonable  assumptions  this 
will  involve  a  net  outflow,  but  the  costs  will  be  small  relative  to 
the  size  of  the  hedge.  Moreover,  these  costs  relate  to  more  than  one 
option  position.  ^'Jhen  the  hedge  begins  it  consists  cf  1/w  options  and 
if  there  are  transaction  cost  savings  at  the  dissolution  of  the  hedge 
it  is  because  the  option  is  in  the  money  at  expiration  and  therefore 
has  a  hedge  ratio  of  one  (i.e.,  equation  (21)  then  relates  to  only 
one  option) . 

Similarly,  a  borrowing  hedge  can  be  formed  without  the  marginal 
cost  of  stock  sales  and  purchases.   In  this  case  an  investor  who  wishes 
to  purchase  a  stock  does  not  purchase  it  immediately,  instead  he  buys 
the  usual  hedged  position  of  w/w  options  and  continuously  rebalances 
as  if  he  actually  held  the  stock.   Eventually  one  of  two  things  happens: 

1)  The  option  price  drops  below  1/16  point  at  which  time  trading 
is  halted.   A  hedge  can  no  longer  be  formed  and  the  stock  is 
finally,  actually,  purchased. 

2)  The  option  is  in  the  money  at  expiration  at  which  time  the 
option  is  exercised  and  the  stock  is  (finally)  acquired. 

Since  transaction  costs  are  the  same  for  buying  and  selling,  equation 
(21)  will  also  describe  the  investor's  costs  for  a  borrowing  hedge.  The  in- 
vestor has,  in  effect,  paid  a(w/w  )  per  share  plus  continuous  rebalancing 


I . 


m 

H 


03 

a) 

o 

•H 
U 

c 
o 

•H 

Q- 
O 

d 
o 

tn 

u 

<2 

C 
•H 
'O 

c 
•a 

•ri 
& 
O  ^ 

o 

pa 

*j 

c 

)-l 

U-l 
U-l 
•H 
Q 

•a 

c 


CO 

o 

u 

c 
o 


o 
to 

en 


u 

H 


o 


o 

M 
0) 


o 


W 
CJ 
M 

P-i 

w 

M 

u 

W 
X 

6a 


60 

c 

•H 
O 

o 


It 


U 


O 


> 
W 
Q 


O 
H 
to 


60 

c 

•H 
CO 

C 


0) 

•-O  -H  <y\ 


^  -a  00 
0)  <:  >w 


*0   -r-)  /-v 


Ooco         oovo         fOi-HO         r^O03         r->-*cn 
OO^T  OI^vO  vO^OO  o^'no  0>CNm 

ooo       oi>JO       CTvO'"^       vT-sTco       <j-<rcsi 


o  o  o 

O   O  <N 

ooo 


O  00  vo 
O  u-l  a^ 
O   O   iH 


m  «3- 


o  o  r«- 

fo  Lo  m 

O   iH   CN 


v£>   00   O  csi   sr   vO 


O    v£)    O  O    CN    r-< 

O    OO    CO  O    O    rH 

OOO  OOO 


I    I 


O    O    CN 

OOO 
OOO 


I    I    I 


o  ON  in 

o  O  i^J 

OOO 


I    I    I 


m  o  00 

iH  sr  iri 
OOO 


I    I    I 


I 


0) 

Q)  13  -H  vO 


73 

Pu  CO 


o 

4J    1-1    CJ  ^^ 
OJ   TJ   -H   <■ 


X>   "O   CN 


I      I 


O   "H  ^ 
O    O    CM 

OOO 


I    I    I 


o  -^  m 
o  o  -a- 

O    CN    00 


I        I       I 


CO  .H  m 

iH   CN   00 
CJ\  00  <■ 


I    I    I 


OOO 
O  O  CN 
OOO 


O    CN  ^ 

O   vO   r^ 

O   O   rH 


CN  sr 


i-l   CM   vo 
CO    -a-    rH 

OOO 


vo   00   O 


O   vO    CTv 

o  vr  CN 

O    CN    >3- 


I    I 


O    rH   vo 

o  o  -a- 
o  o  o 


I    I    I 


o  vo  cy> 

O   vo   iH 
O    CM    O 


I    I 


C3N  CO  O 

^  vo  r^ 
cTv  CO  -a- 


vo  r^  CT\ 

<-    ON    O 

^  O  r^ 


O  O  iH 
OOO 
OOO 


o  r^  o 

O    O    CN 

ooo 


CN  >a- 


-*  in  ON 
■H  ro  sr 

ooo 


vO   00   ov 


CO   cn   00 

<•  vo  r^ 
ooo 


^ 


o  o  ~a- 

O   O   -H 

ooo 


o  00  m 
o  sr  r-~ 

O    O    rM 


ooo 

en    u^    \D 
O    r-(    CN 


o  m  vo 

o  -d-  o 

O    O    rH 


I    I    I 


o  iH  iH       m  -a-  CN 
in  i~>  o\        a^  r-i  en 

ooo  O   rH   rH 


I    I    I 


(^   ro  CO  CN   00   vo 

«a-  -a-  m        o  o  iH 
<f  (T)  r-t        -a-  ro  >H 


CN  -a-  vo 


CTv  Ov  CN 
00  <■  ro 
o  CN  in 


iH   CTV   <• 

<Ti  m  00 
-a-  o  m 


CN  <r  "n 


CO  m  00 

CJv   O   iH 
O   iH   i-H 


O   CO   00 

O   O   iH 
OOO 


(U 

vi   a 

•^    -H 


O  >H  ,H 
O  O  CO 
OOO 


o  iH  m 

O    r-l    CN 
O   CN  00 


m  ON  o 

O  t-^  vO 
Cy>   vo    r-( 


00  CT\  in 

CJN    00    CM 

CO  av  m 


00    CN    CJV 

cjv  m  sr 
CO  ON  »a- 


O.    CO 

i 

^■s 

•H 

C 

H 

o   o 

.^     0) 

o    u 

O    -H 

4J     ;-l 

CO  e- 

<-i  m  ON 


CN  «a- 


iH  m  cjN 


vo  r^  ov 


CM  CO  m 


-.,.W1. 


00 

CN 


-a- 
ro 


o 


iH  m  ON 


vo 
-a- 


iH  m  CJN 


CN 

in 


to 
u 

•H 
U 

c 
o 


Cu 
O 


c 
o 


CO 

iJ 

5 


60 

c 

•H 

a 

0) 

•o 
c 
at 

00 

c 

& 
O 

u 
u 
o 

« 


c 


•a 

c 

CO 


CO 

o 
u 

c 
o 


CJ 
CO 


H 


O 

CO 

u 
u 

0) 

M 


c 


u 

M 

Ci 

p- 
w 

M 
CJ 

cu 

w 


o 


II 

C/D 


=3 
H 
W 


CO 

u 


o 


> 
c 


Q 
H 
c/2 

3 


5^ 


60 

C 
•H 

o 
u 
u 
o 


CM 


60 
C 
-H 
^3 
C 
0) 


■^  -H  C7\ 

o  vo  m 

-a-  iH  a^ 

VO 

00 

I— 1 

m 

CO 

On 

00 

m 

r^ 

C  r--  o 

u-l  (^  a\ 

on 

LO 

o 

in 

ro 

r^ 

On 

m 

1^1 

pa  (4  V-- 

Pu 

O  "H  r--. 

•  •  • 

o  fn  i^ 
•  •  • 

• 

• 

• 

• 

O 

■H 

• 

• 

LO 

^ 

Pi 


c» 


o  <r  ^ 

O  <■  00 
O  O  r-l 


r~  ON  CO 
o  r^  CO 
o  1-1  n 


00  <r  CO 
in  r^  o 
o  <NI  <■ 


^o  cr.  r-C 


en  00  i-i 

CM  CN  i-H 
O  CM  S3- 


•H  C5  T3  ts> 
C  W  <  w 


I   I   I 


O  NO  CM 
O  O  CM 

o  o  o 


I  t  I 


CN  CM  NO 

o  cn  Ln 
o  o  o 


I  I  I 


1^  -a-  00 

CM  NO  00 

o  o  o 


I  I 


>*  CM  00 

m  ON  i-( 

o  O  iH 


I  i  I 


I  I  I 


I  I  I 


I  I  I 


■u  a  0)  m 

P<  CO 


O  CM  u-i 
O  I~^  CO 
O  O  CN 


en  ON  CM 

iH  CO  r^ 

O  CM  U1 


iH  vr  m 


r-»  r-l  o 
t-H  O  CM 
iH  <•  NO 


NO  00  o 


o  ON  r^ 

NO  lO  CM 
O  CM  ^3- 


I  I  I 


I  I  I 


I  I  I 


I  I  I 


CM 


rH  -*  NO 


NO  00  iH 


cd  "^1  ^— \ 

J3  TJ  CM 

01  <  N-' 


4) 

•^    -H    r-i 

PL, 


O  O  LTl 

O  <r  NO 
O  O  i-H 


NO  rH  ON 

O  r~  NO 
O  iH  IT) 


CO  NO  d 

LTi  r^  r-» 
O  CM  <■ 


-*  O  -H 

CM  sr  m 

O  CM  «3- 


CM 


iH  s3-  lO 


vO  00  O 


CM  <■  NO 


iH  un  ON 

O  CN  CO 
O  "H  CM 


I  I  I 


m  <r  o 
ON  CM  m 

O  iH  iH 


I   I   I 


u 

CU 

o 

U-I 

vj- 

m 

o 

en 

o 

C7N  m 

00 

nn 

o 

iH  O 

o  <r 

ID 

"O  tH  NO 

<   u  •^ 

o 

CM 

m 

-si- 

CM 

u-i 

u-> 

■H  >3- 

r^ 

iH 

m 

rn 

• 

• 

in 

• 

O 

• 

• 

• 

• 

O  00 

•   • 

• 

ps. 

• 

NO 

• 

•  • 

• 

CM  ■<)■  NO 


CM  CO  O 

c^  in  NO 

O  O  rH 


I  I  t 


■p  •!-!  a  ,~v 

o 

rs. 

o 

00 

0^ 

00 

r^  iH  in 

00  NO 

00 

CO 

en 

<U  T)  -H  <r 

o 

ON 

-a- 

u-i 

O 

CnI 

NO  CM  NO 

CO  r~ 

r-. 

• 

o 

• 

CO 

• 

O 

• 

• 

ON 

• 

NO  <r  VI- 

•  •  • 

•     « 

O 

• 

• 

CO 

• 

CM  ^  NO 


T) 

1-!^N 

o 

m 

o 

CM 

o 

1-) 

NO  o 

rH 

cn 

NO 

00 

cn  p^ 

c 
1 

<    •— 

O 

o 

CM 

o 

rn 

m 

CM  NO 

00 

U-I 

CO 

o 

CJN  1— 1 

rn 

• 

o 

• 

o 

• 

o 

• 

O 

• 

o 

• 

o  o 

•   • 

O 

• 

o 

• 

o 

• 

iH 

• 

O  rH 

•   • 

iH 

• 

1-1  r>.  pn 
O  rn  r-( 
O  iH  en 


• 

o 

• 
CM 

• 

m 

• 
o 

• 

00 

• 

CO 

• 

•  • 

m  rH 

• 

iH 

•        • 

o  00 

•  • 
0^  vj- 

• 

o 

1/ 1 

m 

tn 

o 

o 

00 

00  r-{ 

NO 

m  en 

ON  <r 

rr» 

o 

• 

rH 

• 

NO 

• 

o 

• 

CM 

• 

m 

• 

• 

O  CJN 

•   • 

<- 

• 

NO  m 

•  • 

en  rH 

•    • 

00 

• 

ime 

Exp 
nths 

H  O  O 

rH  m  ON 

rH  m  CJN 

rH  m  CTN 

rH  m  CJ^ 

r-< 

v_^ 

Stock 
Price 

00 
CM 

o 

s3- 

NO 

CM 

m 

»3-  m 


r-i  ij-t  a^ 


w 


0) 

u 

•H 
Pi 

a 
o 

•H 

D. 
O 

C 

o 
m 
u 

C 
•H 

-a 
c 
a) 

iJ 

c 
td 

M 
C 
•H 

O 
J-i 

o 

PQ 

c 

(U 
!-( 
03 
U-i 

14-1 


•a 
C 
ta 

CO 

u 
en 
o 

u 

c 
o 


o 
ca 
en 
C 
CO 
u 

H 

o 


a 

14-I 

w 


O 


w 
u 

M 

Pi 
p^ 

M 

u 

w 


^2 


c 

•H 

o 
u 
u 
o 

M 


CM 


60 

c 


CO 

<u 
> 

C 


(U 

LO 

iH 

iH 

CN 

in 

CT\ 

P^ 

m 

CO 

m 

CT\ 

P-- 

CO 

t^ 

m 

w 

a  ^^ 

o 

vo 

r^ 

CN 

00 

in 

i-f 

0^ 

iH 

CM 

vj- 

a\ 

m 

VO 

<r 

«3 

•H    CTv 

o 

r^ 

ON 

CN 

in 

m 

n 

p^ 

CM 

00 

iH 

\C 

m 

CM 

r~ 

pa 

Ul   ^^ 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

• 

fl^ 

iH 

CM 

>3- 

CN 

m 

00 

v£> 

O 

CN 

CN 

in 

r-- 

^    "O  00 

Pi 


•H     C    Xl   P^ 


(u  -a 


o 


»4 
Pu 


(1)  c3  /-N 

4J   cj  0)  in 

tt)    -H  1-1  v_^ 

P-l  c/^ 


0) 
(U  T3   -H  sa- 

1^ 


■73   •'-)  ^~\ 


CO      TH  /-N 

XI    TT    CN 

Pi 


0) 

en    u  ^-\ 

•-3    -H    rH 

p- 


iH  .H  r^ 

O    <3-   ^ 

o  "-I  en 


I     I     I 


o  en  00 
o  CN  <r 

o  o  o 


I    I    I 


-J-    00    VO 

o  cTi  m 
o  "~i  "^ 


CM    CM    O 

o  '■o  in 

C   Cs)  \o 


I     I     i 


VD   O  vO 

O    v£!    O 
O   00   CM 


CM 


O   .-H  <t 

o  CM  <r 
o  o  o 


iH  <a-  CM 

o  en  in 
o  iH  m 


in  in  o 

O   O   tH 

o  r^  00 


00  vD  1— I 
CM  CT\  >^ 
O    CM    in 


vD    m    "-D 
00   C\   ^ 

o  en  ^ 


VO    <f    CN 

^o  cTi  r^ 
O  en  vo 


I     I     I 


cr,  in  m 
o  in  CO 
o  o  o 


I     I     I 


<3\  r^  vo 

en  CO  ,-1 
O  O  "H 


I     i     I 


m  vo  i~- 

v£>    iH   «* 
O    "H   iH 


I       I       I 


m  in  vo 

in  en  rH 

CM    CM    Oi 


I        I        I 


CM   CM   r^ 

cj\  iH  en 
iH  en  -a- 


I      I      I 


•*  o>  00 

cTi  m  r~. 

vO   vD    00 


fsi  en 


CM  r~  ,H 

\o  <•  00 
o  m  cTi 


CM  m  r~ 


00  in  vo 

a\  r^  m 

rH  r^   iH 


vo    CJV    rH 


VO   ^  00 

r~-  ON  o 

iH   vO    r-l 


I     I     I 


00  CM  vX> 
iH  CO  ON 
en  P^  CO 


I    I 


O    P~    CN 
CTN    CM    p~ 

en  o  m 


I     I 


o  en  <o 
i~«  en  CO 
CO  en  ON 


CM  «3- 


CT\    CM    00 

o  m  p- 
o  o  o 


CM   vO   00 


00  en  o 
en  00  ,H 

O   O   iH 


vO    O    CN 


>a-  CM  o 

•■o  rH  m 

O    rH    iH 


P--   ON  -3- 

CN  00  m 
o  CM  m 


m  vo  m 

CO    C3N    1^ 

O  en  vo 


p~  en  o 

vo  o  ON 
o  <r  VO 


CN  r-4  in 
CO  <!■  vO 
CN)    <•   CM 


vO    00    O 
vO    ~3-    ON 

CM  in  P-. 


o  00  r^ 

~*    rH    m 
P^  00   iH 


CM   •* 


cvj  m  r^ 


VO  o^  CN 


o  m  in 

CM    Cvj    O 

O  en  VO 


I      I     I 


00   VO   00 

ON  vr  p^ 

O    iH    rH 


I    I    I 


m  vo  CTN 

rH    C3N   in 

<■  r^  ON 


CM   <■   vO 


CJ\  0^  CN 

m  m  vo 

rH    in    ON 


I    I    I 


<!•    -*    rH 

m  m  CN 
m  en  On 


CM  m  p^ 


vO   O   ON 

cjN  sr  vo 

O    rH    rH 


rH   CJN   m 

CM  m  m 

o  en  vO 


vo  in  r^ 
en  r»»  rH 

>a-    00    rH 


a-  to 
^■5 

rH    m    CJN 

rH   m   C3N 

rH    m    ON 

eH    m    CJN 

rH 

Stock 
Price 

CO 
CN 

^ 

o 

>3- 

vO 
»3- 

CNl 

m 

CM  ^  r^ 


rH  m  Ov 


-10- 


costs  to  postpone  the  cost  of  acquiring  the  stock  and  save  a  w*   (per 
share)  when  the  stock  is  finally  acquired. 

Since  the  continuously  rebalanced  option  hedge  position  mimics 
every  price  movement  of  the  underlying  stock,  the  investor  has,  in 
effect  bought  the  stock  immediately  without  paying  for  the  stock  until 
the  option  expires  or  becomes  worthless.  This  procedure  is  therefore 
a  substitute  for  margin  borrowing  but  without  a  margin  requirement  (or 
collateral  in  the  usual  sense  of  the  word). 

IV.   The  Combined  Effects  of  Transaction  Costs  and  Different  Borrowing 
and  Lending  Rates 

The  effects  of  transaction  costs  and  different  borrowing  and  lending 
rates  are  presented  in  Tables  1,  2,  and  3.   Column  (1)  is  the  Black-Scholes 
option  price  calculated  under  the  assumptions  specified  in  the  table. 
Column  (9)  is  the  value  the  Black-Scholes  model  gives  if  the  specified 
borrowing  rate  is  substituted  for  the  risk  free  rate.  The  common  stock 
standard  deviations  listed  in  the  tables  roughly  correspond  to  the  10th, 
50th  and  90th  deciles  of  the  standard  deviations  observed  by  Whaley 
(1982). 

Columns  (2)  and  (8)  ("Rebal  Ad j ")  are  the  difference  between  the 
traditional  B&S  option  price  and  the  daily  (i.e,  At  =  1/260)  rebalancing 
transaction  cost  price  derived  in  Section  II.   In  addition  to  the  assump- 
tions specified  in  the  table,  one  way  transaction  costs  for  options  are 
assumed  to  be  2"  and  the  underlying  stock's  expected  return  is  17%  per  year. 


INSERT  TABLES  1-3  ABOUT  HERE 


r  t. 


-11- 

ColLimns  (3)  and  (7)  ("Init-End  Adj")  are  estimates  of  the  adjust- 
ment to  the  option  price  required  to  cover  the  cost  of  acquiring  the 
hedge  and  finally  liquidating  it.   These  costs  are  based  on  the  trading 
techniques  presented  in  the  previous  section  and  embodied  in  equation  (21). 
Common  stock  transaction  costs  (a   )  are  assumed  to  be  1.25%  and  option 
transaction  costs  (a)  are  assumed  to  be  2%.   The  expected  value  of  the 
future  value  of  the  option  is  calculated  from  Sprenkle's  equation  (see 
Smith,  1976,  page  17)  and  this  value  is  discounted  back  to  the  present 
using  a  discount  rate,  K,  derived  from  the  CAPM  under  the  assumptions 
that  the  market  return  is  17%  per  year,  the  risk  free  rate  is  12%,  the 
beta  of  the  underlying  stock  is  one  and  the  beta  of  the  option  (as  pointed 

Q 

out  by  Black  and  Scholes,  1972)  is: 

Columns  (4)  and  (6)  ("Net  Adj  Price")  are  Black  &  Scholes  option 
prices  (columns  (1)  and  (7))  with  both  types  of  transaction  costs  added 
(for  the  investment  hedge,  columns  (2)  and  (3))  or  subtracted  (for  the 
borrowing  hedge,  columns  (7)  and  (8)).   Columns  (4)  and  (6)  therefore  show 

the  prices  the  options  must  sell  for  to  net  the  specified  borrowing 

9 

and  lending  rates  after  transaction  costs.   Needless  to  say,  these 

transaction  costs  would  be  different  for  different  sets  of  assumptions. 
The  costs  presented  are  illustrative  and  can  be  helpful  in  understanding 
the  nature  of  the  phenomena.   The  reader  is  encouraged  to  analyse  the 
effects  of  his  own  assumptions. 

Column  (5)  ("Net  Price  Spread")  is  the  result  of  subtracting 
column  (4)  from  column  (6).   It  should  be  interpreted  as  follows: 


-12- 


1)  Negative  values  indicate  that  the  option  price  is  the  bounded 
range  betv^7een  the  prices  specified  in  colurans  (4)  and  (6). 
For  option  prices  within  this  range  neither  investment  hedges 
nor  borrowing  hedges  are  particularly  attractive.   The  reader 
will  note  that  the  highest  option  price  which  produces  an 
attractive  borrowing  hedge  (Column  (6),  Net  Adj  Price  -  Borrowing) 
is  frequently  higher  than  the  traditional  Black-Scholes  price 
(Column  (1)).  When  this  occurs,  the  Black-Scholes  price  isn't 

an  equilibrium  value.  If  an  option  sells  for  the  Black-Scholes 
price,  excess  profits  can  be  made  by  forming  a  borrowing  hedge 
and  (in  effect)  borrowing  at  below  the  market  rate. 

2)  A  zero  value  indicates  a  unique  equilibrium  option  price  (i.e., 
the  value  shown  in  both  column  (6)  and  column  (4)).  This  oc- 
curs when  transaction  cost  effects  and  borrowing  and  lending 
effects  precisely  cancel.   This  unique  option  price  is  never 
the  Black-Scholes  price  except  in  the  trivial  case  where  all 
prices  are  zero. 

3)  A  positive  value  indicates  that  the  option  hedge  can  be  viewed 
as  a  financial  intermediary  with  a  lower  spread  than  traditional 
intermediaries.   If  the  option  sells  at  a  price  between  the  prices 
specified  in  columns  (4)  and  (6)  the  option  hedge  is  simultaneously 
a  higher  return  risk  free  investment  than  treasury  bills  and  a 
lower  cost  source  of  funds  than  traditional  borrowing.   In  this 
case,  there  is  n£  price  to  which  the  option  can  adjust  which  will 
eliminate  excess  profits.   For  example,  if  the  option  price  were 

to  drop  low  enough  for  the  investment  hedge  to  no  longer  be  attrac- 
tive, this  would  only  make  a  borrowing  hedge  even  better.   It  may 
be  that  the  only  thing  that  prevents  all  short  term  borrowing  and 
lending  from  being  sucked  into  these  financial  "black  holes"  is  the 
limited  number  of  investors  in  the  special  transaction  cost  situa- 
tions described  in  the  previous  section. 

This  permanent  disequilibrium  is  bounded  between  the  column 
(6)  and  column  (4)  prices.   If  the  option  price  is  above  the 
column  (6)  price  the  option  is  not  attractive  as  a  part  of  a 
borrowing  hedge  but  a  short  position  in  the  option  will  be 
very  desirable  as  part  of  an  investment  hedge.  This  unbal- 
anced selling  pressure  should  drive  the  option  price  below 
the  column  (6)  price  at  which  time  the  option  is  desirable  as 
both  an  investment  hedge  and  a  borrowing  hedge.   This  presum- 
ably results  in  a  better  balance  between  supply  and  demand  for 
the  option. 

Similarly,  if  the  option  were  to  sell  below  the  column  (4) 
price  it  would  be  very  attractive  as  a  part  of  a  borrowing 
hedge  but  there  would  be  no  interest  in  forming  investment 


-13- 

hedges .   The  resulting  net  buying  pressure  should  push  the 
option  price  back  above  the  column  (4)  value. 

Therefore,  when  the  column  (5)  value  is  positive,  it  indicates 
a  bizarre  form  of  bounded  disequilibrium. 

Transaction  costs  and  different  borrowing  and  lending  rates  may  help 
to  explain  some  empirical  anomalies.  Specifically: 

Some  empirical  findings  contradict  each  other.  For  example,  Black 
(1976)  vs.  Macbeth  and  Merville  (1979)  on  the  direction  of  the  bias  for 
in  the  money,  relative  to  out  of  the  money  options.  This  paper  shows  that 
options  usually  have  a  range  of  equilibrium  (or  bounded  disequilibrium) 
values.   It  is  therefore  not  surprising  that  studies  which  assume  unique 
equilibrium  values  sometimes  contradict  each  other. 

Merton  (1976)  says  that  practitioners  believe  that  the  B-S  model  under- 
prices  both  in  the  money  and  out  of  the  money  options.  Latane  and 
Rendleman  (1976)  conclude  that  "...  the  preponderance  of  evidence  would 
be  toward  options  being  over  priced."  (i.e.,  the  B-S  price  is  too  low). 
Tables  1,  2  and  3  show  that  when  the  transaction  cost/interest  rate  effect 
is  considered,  the  B-S  price  (column  (1))  is  in  the  lower  portion  or 
entirely  below  the  equilibrium  range  of  option  values.   Empirical  tests 
should  show  that  the  B-S  model  underprices  options.   It  does. 

Although  empirical  results  conflict,  the  more  modem,  sophisticated 
and  exhaustive  studies  seem  to  show  that  the  B-S  model  underprices  in 
the  money  options  relative  to  out  of  the  money  options  (see  Macbeth  and 
Merville,  1979)  and  underprices  options  on  low  risk  stocks  relative  to 
high  risk  stocks  (see  Whaley,  1982). 

This  is  the  average  effect  a  combination  of  transaction  costs  and 
divergent  interest  rates  should  produce.   If  the  effect  of  different 


-14- 

borrowing  and  lending  rates  is  large  relative  to  the  size  of  transaction 
costs  (Tables  1,  2  and  3  and  others  calculated  by  the  authors  suggest 
this  is  the  case  for  options  which  are  in  the  money  and/or  written  on  low 
variance  stocks)  the  B-S  price  will  be  near  the  bottom  of,  or  below 
the  range  of  equilibrium  prices.   Therefore,  the  B-S  model  will  be  found 
to  underprice  these  options.   On  the  other  hand,  options  for  which  the 
interest  rate  effect  is  small  relative  to  the  transaction  cost  effect 
(out  of  the  money  options  and  options  on  high  variance  stocks),  the  B-S 
price  will  be  near  the  center  of  the  equilibrium  range  and  such  options 
may  appear  overpriced  for  one  sample  and  underpriced  for  another;  thus 
explaining  the  conflicting  results  in  the  literature.   However,  for  these 
options  the  Black-Scholes  price  is  near  the  middle  of  the  equilibrium 
range  so,  on  average  (and  presumably  for  large  sample  sizes),  the  B-S 
price  may  be  a  relatively  unbiased  description.   Therefore,  the  transaction 
cost/interest  rate  model  may  help  to  explain  Macbeth  and  Mervilles'  (1979) 
and  I'Jhaley's  (1982)  observed  biases;  but  the  transaction  cost/interest 
rate  model  suggests  that  the  range  of  biases  is  more  likely  to  extend 
from  the  (roughly)  correctly  priced  to  the  underpriced  rather  than  from 

the  overpriced  to  the  underpriced;  a  distinction  their  weighted  implied 

12 
standard  deviation  techniques  would  have  difficulty  detecting. 

V.   Conclusion 

When  transaction  costs  and  different  borrowing  and  lending  rates  are 
taken  into  consideration,  options  (in  general)  take  on  a  range  of  equilib- 
rium values.   The  traditional  Black-Scholes  price  is  in  the  bottom  portion 


-15- 

of,  or  entirely  below,  this  range.   These  observations  are  used  to  explain 
empirical  anomalies  found  in  the  option  pricing  literature. 

The  paper  also  makes  the  startling  observation  that  for  in  the  money 
options  on  low  variance  stocks,  there  may  be  no  equilibrium  option  price. 
Any  price  these  options  might  assume  will  offer  a  risk  free  investment 
at  above  the  risk  free  rate  or  borrowing  at  below  the  market  rate  or 
both  simultaneously.   The  option  exchange  becomes  society's  lowest 

spread  financial  intermediary.   All  short  term  borrowing  and  lending 

13 
might  be  sucked  into  these  financial  "black  holes"    were  it  not 

for  the  special  nature  of  the  situations  needed  to  produce  low  enough 

transaction  costs. 


i . 


-16- 


Appendix  A 

The  Implications  of  Hedge  Rebalancing  Using  Adjustments 
to  the  Option  Position 

Throughout  this  paper  the  authors  assume  that  rebalancing  is  done 
by  adjusting  the  option  portion  of  the  hedge.   This  is  generally  the 
cheapest  way  to  rebalance  because  option  rebalancing  involves  smaller 
dollar  amounts  than  rebalancing  with  common  stock.   This  cost  advantage 
is  partially  offset  by  the  fact  that  the  average  bid-ask  spread  in  the 
options  market  is  greater  than  in  the  stock  market  (see  Phillips  and 
Smith,  1980). 

The  hedge  acquisition  and  dissolution  techniques  described  in 
the  text  assume  that  the  hedge  contains  the  same  number  of  shares  of 
stock  at  the  beginning  and  end  of  the  life  of  the  hedge.   Therefore, 
equation  (24)  will  only  (usually)  be  an  accurate  description  of  costs 
if  all  rebalancing  is  done  with  options  (thus  leaving  the  number  of 
shares  in  the  hedge  unchanged  throughout  the  life  of  the  hedge) . 

Needless  to  say,  an  investor  should  not  rebalance  by  buying  an 
overpriced  option  or  selling  an  underpriced  option.  Therefore,  the 
assumption  that  all  rebalancing  is  done  with  options  is  unrealistic. 

However,  one  suspects  that  the  advantage  of  being  able  to  rebalance 
with  options  when  they  are  favorably  priced  and  avoid  them  (with  stock 
rebalancing)  when  they  are  unfavorably  priced  more  than  offsets  the 
additional  rebalancing  cost  of  common  stock  rebalancing  and  the  addi- 
tional hedge  dissolution  cost  which  may  result  from  acquiring  an 
unwanted  common  stock  position  to  liquidate  at  the  end  of  the  life  of 
the  hedge.   Moreover,  common  stock  rebalancing  can  also  result  in 


-17- 

the  acquisition  of  part  of  the  desired  stock  position  prior  to  dis- 
solution thus  reducing  costs  below  those  assumed  in  equation  (24). 

Moreover,  footnote  10  shows  how  some  investors  can  reduce  trans- 
action costs  to  a  level  generally  below  those  presented  in  this  paper. 
Finally,  the  reader  may  feel  that  the  option  rebalancing  assumption 
is  unrealistic  because  it  is  not  possible  to  trade  options  in  odd  lots. 
The  authors  suggest  that  this  is  not  a  real  problem  because,  if  the 
investor's  hedge  is  so  small  that  rebalancing  involves  trades  of  less 
than  several  thousand  dollars  each,  transaction  costs  will  destroy  the 
investor  no  matter  how  he  rebalances. 


1  •  ;. 


-18- 

Appendi:-:  3 

A  Demonstration  of  the  Validity  of  the  Proposed  Solution  to  Equation  (9). 

The  authors  present  this  example  in  hopes  of  convincing  the  reader 
that  the  proposed  solution  to  equation  (6)    is  correct.   In  order  to  pro- 
vide a  simple  example,  the  authors  have  chosen  parameters  which  are 
realistic  but  relatively  easy  to  calculate: 
X  =  $50 
c  =  $50 
v^  =  .25 
Ct*  -  t)  =  .5  (years) 
r  =  .10 
6  =  .15 
a  =  .01 
The  g  function  (equation  (11))  on  the  right  side  of  equation  (6) 
is  the  dollar  amount  of  rebalancing  required.   It  can  be  calculated 
from  Black  &  Sholes  pricing  theory  based  on  the  parameters  listed  above. 
This  yields: 

w  =  8.1316 


1-  =  (In  ^+  (r  +  .5v2)(t*  -  t))/(v2(t*  -  t))^^^   =  . 
1       c 


31820 


w^  =  N(d^)  =  .62483 


For  simplicity  define 

m  =  d^/{2)^^~   =  .225 


-19- 


w-,-,    can   then  be   expressed  as: 


w^^  =   6-°^  /CxvCZirCt*   -   t))^'^^) 


=    .02145 


Also: 

2  2 

"l2  "    CCln^)/Ct*  -  t)   -  r  -  ^)(e"'"  ) )/ C2vC2TrCt*  -   t))^' h 

=  -.12068 

2 
w^^^  =  -e"^   Cv/C2Ct*  -  t))^''^  +  m/Ct*  -   t))/ CvVtt^/^) 

=  -.00081523 

Substituting  these  values  into  equation  0.1)    of  the  paper  and  assuming 
daily  rebalancing  (i.e.,  At  =  1/260)  yields: 

g  =  89.82      .     .,         ;  ^     ,.  ■       ^  ,:.::    ■ 
(the  approximation  listed  in  footnote  4  yields  89.76). 
The  right  side  of  equation  (6)  is  therefore:  .  ■, 

ag  =  .8982 

The  left  side  of  equation  (6)  includes  partial  derivatives  of  the 
daily  rebalancing  transaction  cost  option  price  derived  in  this  paper. 
These  derivatives  must  be  approximated  by  taking  small  interval  values 
about  the  $50  stock  price  and  the  .5  year  time  to  expiration: 


-20- 


Estimation  Estimated 

Parameter                         Interval  Value 

w                                          8.4503 

$50  +  $.50  .63184 

$50  +  $2.00  .02033 

.5  year  +  .005  year  -9.5952 


"l 


^1 


^2 

The  width  of  the  interval  (column  2  above)  used  to  approximate 
each  partial  derivative  is  a  function  of  the  5  to  6  significant  digit 
accuracy  of  the  option  price,  w,  as  calculated  from  the  numerical  methods 
solution  to  equation  (17). 

When  the  estimated  values  from  column  3  above  are  substituted  into 
the  left  side  of  equation  (6)  they  yield  .9278.   Considering  the  inherent 
inaccuracy  of  small  interval  approximations,  this  seems  to  be  a  good 
approximation  of  the  value  previously  calculated  for  the  right  side  of 
equation  (6)  (i.e.,  they  differ  by  less  than  4%). 


1 

Footnotes 
Thorpe  (1973)  demonstrated  that  option  hedges  can  be  sources  of 
funds  despite  restrictions  on  short  selling. 

These  results  are  derived  under  the  assumption  that  rebalancing 
is  done  by  buying  or  selling  options  (rather  than  stock).   See  Appendix 
A  for  a  discussion  of  the  implications  of  this  assumption. 

3 
Discrete  rebalancing  interval  applications  of  the  continuous 

time  option  pricing  model  seem  to  pose  no  great  problem.  Boyle  and 
Bnanuel  (1980)  have  demonstrated  that  the  risk  created  by  short  interval 
rebalancing  is  uncorrelated  with  the  market;  and  Rubenstein  (1976)  and 
Brennan  (1979)  have  demonstrated  that  discrete  interval  applications 
of  the  Black-Scholes  model  will  be  valid  under  assumptions  of  constant 
proportional  risk  aversion  and  a  bivariate  lognormal  distribution  be- 
tween market  and  underlying  asset  returns.  ,  .  ■  • 

4 

The  RHS  of  (7)  is  evaluated  by  separating  the  term  inside  the 

absolute  value  into  a  positive  lognormal  distribution  truncated  at  zero 
and  a  negative  lognormal  distribution  truncated  at  zero.   Sprenkle's 
formula  (see  Smith  (1976),  pp.  17)  is  used  to  evaluate  the  expectation 
of  each  truncated  distribution  and  the  absolute  values  of  these  ex- 
pectations are  then  added.  ..  -  ,,^ 

For  rebalancing  intervals  of  one  day  or  less  and  common  stock 
standard  deviations  of  .3  (annual)  or  more,  the  procedure  can  be  greatly 
simplified.   In  this  case,  the  first  term  inside  the  absolute  value 
(which  represents  short  term  stock  fluctuations)  will  be  much  greater 
than  the  other  terns  (which  represent  longer  term  shifts  in  hedge  ratio). 


-22- 

g  can  then  be  approximated  by  applying  the  formula  for  a  full  wave  linear 
detector: 

g  =  E  I  Ax/x  I  xww,,/(w,dt)  '=  C2a  dt/Tr)    xww^^/w,dt 

\^en  an  option  is  exercized  the  commission  is  based  on  the 
exercise  price  not  the  stock  price.  Therefore  the  investor  pays 
a  MinCx-^jc)  when  the  hedge  is  terminated. 

6 

One  problem  with  the  Black  Scholes  model  is  its  dependence  on 

the  assumption  that  short  positions  in  common  stock  are  an  immediate 
source  of  funds.   Thorpe  (1973)  has  argued  that  if  an  investor  currently 
owns  the  stock  for  which  a  hedge  is  to  be  created,  selling  the  stock 
is  equivalent  to  short  selling  and  _i£  a  source  of  funds.   The  procedure 
for  forming  a  minimum  transaction  cost  borrowing  hedge  described  in 
this  paper  is  another  way  in  which  a  borrowing  hedge  can  be  a  source 
of  funds. 

The  reader  is  encouraged  to  make  his  own  transaction  cost 
assimiptions.   The  rebalancing  adjustment  is  approximately  proportional 
to  the  transaction  cost  rate,  a  throughout  the  relevant  range  of  values 
and  the  initiation  and  ending  transaction  costs  can  be  approximated 
from  equations  (21)  and  (22). 

The  transaction  costs  used  to  create  Tables  1,  2  and  3  were  chosen 
to  illustrate  the  lower  end  of  the  reasonable  range  of  costs.   For 
example,  the  2%  transaction  cost  rate  for  options  can  be  interpreted 
as  the  rate  for  an  investor  who  has  1.1%  (one  way)  transaction  costs, 
who  is  investing  in  an  option  series  with  an  average  bid-ask  spread  of 


-23- 

\ 

3%  Cabout  the  35th  percentile  of  the  option  spreads  observed  by  Phillips 
and  Smith,  1980)  for  which  40%  of  the  trades  require  no  market  maker 
involvement  and  a  zero  spread  (Phillips  and  Roberts,  1979).   Thus  yielding 
a  one  way  spread  cost  of  3%  x  .6  x  .5  =  .9%  and  an  average  total  trading 
cost  of  2%.   Similarly,  the  1.25%  common  stock  transaction  cost  rate  can 
be  interpreted  as  1%  transaction  costs  plus  a  one  way  average  spread  of 
.25%  i,±.e.,    the  total  spread,  including  the  probability  of  specialist 
involvement  is  .5%). 

Equation  C22)  describes  an  option's  beta  at  a  specific  instant  in 
time  and  is  therefore  only  an  approximation  of  the  beta  actually  needed. 
Fortunately,  beta  is  only  used  to  calculate  the  discount  rate  to  be 
applied  to  a  small  amount  of  money  to  be  realized  a  short  time  in  the 
future.   Therefore,  more  precision  is  probably  unnecessary. 

9 

In  effect  Tables  1,  2  and  3  assume  that  the  costs  of  initiating 

and  terminating  the  option  hedge  are  prepaid  by  adding  or  subtracting 
them  from  the  initial  option  price.   This  change  in  initial  option 
price  will  slightly  alter  rebalancing  transaction  costs  and  is  not 
taken  into  consideration  in  the  derivation  of  the  continuous  rebalancing 
model  (equations  (1)  through  (19)). 

Given  the  generally  small  size  of  initiation  and  termination  costs 
relative  to  the  option  price,  and  the  approximate  nature  of  other  aspects 
of  the  option  pricing  model,  this  should  be  acceptable  for  most  purposes. 

Some  investors  will  be  able  to  reduce  transaction  costs  to  levels 
below  those  assumed  in  this  paper  by  rebalancing  less  frequently.   For 


-24- 

a  borrowing  hedge  using  the  acquisition  and  dissolution  technique  sug- 
gested in  the  paper,  a  failure  to  rebalance  means  that  the  equivalent 
number  of  shares  being  mimicked  by  the  option  position  changes  as  the 
hedge  ratio  changes  but  is  not  immediately  rebalanced  (i.e.,  the 
investor  may  have  the  option  equivalent  of  96  shares  rather  than  the 
100  shares  he  originally  intended,  etc.)*   Some  investors  may  not  care 
about  the  exact  number  of  common  stock  equivalents  his  option  position 
equals.   If  not,  he  can  save  money  by  rebalancing  only  after  the  hedge 
ratio  has  changed  substantially.   He  can  then  avoid  the  transaction  costs 
resulting  from  all  of  the  reversals  of  the  hedge  ratio  occurring  between 
rebalancing.   Moreover,  this  strategy  allows  the  investor  to  save  money 
by  rebalancing  in  larger  amounts. 

The  same  less  frequent  rebalancing  strategy  can  be  applied  to  the  in- 
vestment hedge  strategy  described  in  the  paper  except  that  in  this 
case  a  failure  to  rebalance  means  that  the  investor  will  have  a  small 
long  or  short  position  in  the  stock  he  originally  wished  to  sell  (i.e., 
instead  of  having  the  equivalent  of  no  stock,  his  equivalent  position 
might  fluctuate  between  long  and  short  positions  amounting  to  a  few 
percent  of  his  original  holding.) 

The  existence  of  these  bounded  disequilibrium  situations  is  not 
particularly  sensitive  to  the  assumptions  used  to  create  Tables  1,  2  and 
3.   For  example,  the  phenomenon  does  not  disappear  even  if  the  transaction 
cost  rate  is  doubled.   Moreover,  if  the  bid-ask  spread  is  positively  cor- 
related to  the  risk  of  the  option,  the  options  exhibiting  bounded  disequilib- 
rium should  have  unusually  low  transaction  costs  because  of  their  low  vari- 
ances (i.e.,  they  are  deep  in  the  money  options  on  low  variance  stocks). 


-25- 

12 

The  weighted  implied  standard  deviation  (WISD)  technique 

explicitly  (as  in  Macbeth  and  Merville,  1979)  or  implicitly  O-Jhaley, 

1982)  assumes  the  average  option  is  correctly  priced.   This  technique 

is  therefore  excellent  at  detecting  relative  biases  but  ill  suited  to 
detecting  biases  effecting  all  options. 

13 

No  pun  intended. 


-26- 


References 

1.  F.  Black  and  M.  Scholes,  "The  Pricing  of  Options  and  Corporate 
Liabilities,"  Journal  of  Political  Econoay  (May-June,  1973),  pp. 
637-659. 

2.  P.  Boyle  and  0.  Emanuel,  "Discretely  Adjusted  Option  Hedges," 
Journal  of  Financial  Economics  (September,  1980),  pp.  259-282. 

3.  M.  Brennan,  "The  Pricing  of  Contingent  Claims  in  Discrete  Time 
Models,"  Journal  of  Finance  (March,  1979),  pp.  53-68. 

4.  E.  Butkov,  Mathematical  Physics  (Addison  Wesley  1968). 

5.  H.  Latane  and  R.  Rendleman,  "Standard  Deviation  of  Stock  Price 
Ratios  Implied  by  Option  Prices,"  Journal  of  Finance,  (May,  1976), 
pp.  369-381. 

6.  J.  Macbeth  and  L.  Merville,  "An  Empirical  Examination  of  the 
Black-Scholes  Call  Option  Pricing  Model,"  Journal  of  Economics, 
(December,  1979),  pp.  1173-1186. 

7.  R.  Merton,  "Option  Pricing  When  Underlying  Stock  Returns  are  Dis- 
continuous ,"  j£umal_of_^|i^ian£ial_Ecor^^     (January /March,  1976), 
pp.  125-144. 

8.  S.  Phillips  and  D.  Roberts,  "Analysis  of  Dually  Listed  Options," 
Unpublished  manuscript  (University  of  Iowa,  Iowa  City,  Iowa). 

9.  S.  Phillips  and  C,  Smith,  "Trading  Costs  for  Listed  Options,"  Journal 
of  Financial  Economics.  Vol.  8  (June,  1980),  pp.  179-201. 

10.  M.  Rubenstein,  "The  Valuation  of  Uncertain  Income  Streams  and  the 
Pricing  of  Options,"  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management 
Science  (1976),  pp.  407-425. 

11.  C.  Smith,  "Option  Pricing  (A  Review),"  Journal  of  Financial  Economics, 
Vol.  3  (March,  1976),  pp.  3-51. 

12.  E.  Thorpe,  "Extensions  of  the  Black-Scholes  Option  Model,"  39th  Session 
of  the  International  Statistical  Institute  (Vienna,  Austria). 

13.  R.  Whaley,  "Valuation  of  American  Call  Options  or  Dividend- Paying 
Stocks:  Empirical  Tests,"  Journal  of  Financial  Economics  (March, 
1982),  pp.  29-58. 


M/E/228 


ECKMAN 

NDERY  INC. 

JUNSS 

I  -To-Plos?  N  MANCHESTER. 
INDIANA  46962