Skip to main content

Full text of "Elements Of Public Administration"

See other formats


THE  BOOK  WAS 
DRENCHED 


JNIVERSAI 
LIBRARY 

03  ? 

OU  164684  |m 

*% 

OUF-7S1—  24-4-8I—  10,000. 

OSMANIA  UNIVERSITY  LIBRARY 
Gill  No.    3  5  C  Accesdon  No. 

Author      r\  ^  1  £ 


1'his  book  shouU  late  fat   marked    below 


ELEMENTS 

OF 


ministration 


JAMES  W.  FESLER  FRITZ  MORSTEIN  MARX 

GEORGE  A.  GRAHAM  DON  K.  PRICE 

V.  O.  KEY,  JR.  HENRY  REINING,  JR. 

AVERY  LEISERSON  WALLACE  S.  SAYRE 

MILTON  M.  MANDELL  DONALD  C.  STONE 

HARVEY  C.  MANSFIELD  JOHN  A.  VIEG 

JOHN  D.  MILLETT  DWIGHT  WALDO 


Edited  By 

FRITZ  MORSTEIN  MARX 


NEW  YORK 
PRENTICE  -  HALL  -  INC. 


Copyright,  1946,  by 

PRENTICE-HALL,  INC. 

70  Fifth   Avenue,  New  Yor/< 

All  rights  reserved.     No  part  of  this  boot^   may  be 

reprinted    in     any    form,    by     mimeograph     or    any 

other    means,    without    permission    in    writing    from 

the  publishers. 


First  printing  November,  1946 
Siioml  punting  ..  Fcbnun,  l(H7 
Third  printing  NoM-rnher,  1^48 
Fourth  printing November,  1949 


PRINTED   IN*   THK   UNITFD   STATFS  OF  AMERICA 


TO 

OUR  STUDENTS 
PERPETUAL  PROMPTERS  OF  THOUGHT 


Preface 


THIS  book  is  a  testimonial  to  its  publisher's  persistence.  Idle  minds 
have  always  liked  to  toy  with  ideas  for  books  that  "ought  to  be  written." 
However  alluring  any  such  plan,  its  author  is  apt  to  consider  it  highly 
unfair  to  be  burdened  with  its  execution.  The  editor  could  have  done 
wonders  with  his  lawn  had  he  managed  to  cling  to  the  role  of  the 
gratuitous  book-planner.  For  better  or  for  worse,  the  publisher  prodded 
him  into  a  more  exacting  job. 

This  book  is  also  a  demonstration  of  teamwork.  The  fourteen  men 
who  came  together  to  form  the  team  discovered  that  they  thought  very 
much  alike  about  the  field  of  interest  they  had  in  common.  When  they 
joined  forces,  all  of  them  were  engaged  in  the  practical  business  of  public 
administration;  all  of  them  were  under  the  influence  of  fresh  experience; 
and  all  of  them  were  stimulated  by  new  insights  that  open  up  to  those 
placed  strategically  within  the  administrative  structure. 

These  exceptional  circumstances  held  forth  the  promise  of  a  unified 
and  systematic  treatment  of  the  subject  rather  than  a  symposium  made  up 
of  unconnected  essays.  In  the  exchange  of  views  among  the  members  of 
the  team,  the  preliminary  plan  grew  into  an  integrated  enterprise  to 
which  each  member  contributed  his  carefully  defined  share.  Throughout 
the  writing  of  the  book,  its  character  as  a  combined  operation  was  sus- 
tained by  the  team  spirit  of  each  participant. 

The  principal  aim  of  the  book  is  to  deepen  the  reader's  understand- 
ing of  the  administrative  process  as  an  integral  phase  of  contemporary 
civilization.  In  a  sense,  therefore,  this  is  a  broadly  political  rather  than 
merely  technical  study.  Its  focus  is  on  the  fundamental  problems  of 
public  administration — the  problems  that  assert  themselves  at  countless 
points  within  the  framework  of  governmental  effort.  The  analysis  here 
presented  attempts  to  explore  both  the  range  of  controlling  institutional 
factors  and  the  variables  of  administrative  behavior. 

The  aim  of  the  book  compelled  an  approach  appropriate  to  it.  A 
glance  at  the  table  of  contents  will  show  that  the  customary  division  of 
the  subject  matter  has  been  modified  in  several  important  respects.  There 
is  also  a  deliberate  recurrence  of  basic  themes,  each  being  developed  in 
progressive  specificity  as  the  discussion  moves  forward.  One  of  these 
basic  themes  inevitably  runs  through  the  entire  volume — that  of  the  im- 


viii  PREFACE 

plications  of  democratic  governance  for  public  management  in  all  of  its 
ramifications. 

Many  good  friends  have  been  generous  enough  to  support  the  team 
at  various  junctures  with  sound  counsel  and  welcome  assistance.  To  name 
them  all  would  make  a  long  list.  The  editor  is  particularly  grateful  for 
the  unfailing  help  rendered  him  by  his  secretary,  Raye  R.  Schwciger. 
Mary  Friedrich  and  Betty  I.  Bleichncr  of  the  reference  staff  of  the  Library 
of  the  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  have  given  liberally  of  their 
bibliographical  knowledge.  The  distinguished  record  officer  of  the  same 
agency,  Helen  L.  Chatficld,  as  an  act  of  supererogation  turned  herself 
into  a  painstaking  proofreader.  All  these  expressions  of  sympathetic 
interest  are  sincerely  appreciated. 

FRITZ  MORSTEIN  MARX 
Washington,  D.  C. 


Introducing  the  Team 


James  W.  Fcsler,  a  former  research  fellow  of  the  Brookings  Institution  and 
the  Rockefeller  Foundation,  is  protessor  of  political  science  at  the  University 
of  North  Carolina.  In  the  federal  government  he  has  served  on  the  staffs  of 
the  National  Resources  Committee,  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative 
Management,  the  Office  of  Production  Management,  the  War  Production  Board, 
and  the  Civilian  Production  Administration.  From  1941  to  1943  he  was 
special  assistant  to  the  executive  secretary  of  OPM  and  WPB;  from  1943  to 
1946  he  headed  the  Policy  Analysis  and  Records  Branch  of  WPB  and  later  of 
CPA,  combining  with  his  duties  during  the  last  two  years  those  of  the  War 
Production  Board's  historian.  His  main  writings  are  Executive  Management 
and  the  Federal  Field  Service  (1937),  one  of  the  special  studies  sponsored  by 
the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management;  and  The  Independ- 
ence of  State  Regulatory  Agencies  (1942). 

George  A.  Graham,  professor  of  politics  at  Princeton  University,  has  also 
taught  at  the  University  of  Illinois  and  at  Monmouth  College.  He  has  been 
associated  with  the  Detroit  Bureau  of  Governmental  Research  and  the  Princeton 
Local  Government  Survey.  In  1942  he  joined  the  Administrative  Management 
Division  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Office  of  the  President.  In 
1943  he  was  made  chief  of  the  War  Supply  Section,  and  subsequently  also  served 
as  head  of  the  War  Records  Section.  In  1945  he  was  placed  in  charge  of  the 
Government  Organization  Branch.  His  publications  include  Special  Assess- 
ments in  Detroit  (1931);  Pe  sonnel  Practices  in  Business  and  Governmental 
Organization  (1935),  one  of  the  monographs  of  the  Commission  of  Inquiry  on 
Public  Service  Personnel;  Education  for  Public  Administration  (1941);  and  Reg- 
ulatory Administration  (1943),  of  which  he  was  co-editor. 

V.  O.  Key,  Jr.,  professor  of  political  science  at  Johns  Hopkins  University,  has 
been  a  staff  member  of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board  and  a  con- 
sultant to  the  Social  Security  Board.  In  the  immediate  prewar  period  he  also 
served  as  a  member  of  the  Baltimore  Commission  on  Governmental  Efficiency 
and  Economy.  During  World  War  II  he  was  associated  with  the  Adminis- 
trative Management  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Office 
of  the  President.  I  le  is  the  author  of  The  Administration  of  Federal  Grants 
to  States  (1937)  and  Politics,  Parties  and  Pressure  Groups  (1942);  and  co-author 
of  The  Initiative  and  the  Referendum  in  California  (1939).  One  of  his  more 
recent  contributions  to  the  periodicals  of  politics  and  public  administration  is 
"The  Reconversion  Pha^e  of  Demobilization,"  American  Political  Science  Review, 
December,  1944. 

Avery  Leiserson,  of  the  political  science  faculty  at  the  University  of  Chicago, 
has  been  a  stafT  member  of  the  Labor  Advisory  Board  of  the  National  Indus- 
trial Recovery  Admininration  in  the  early  New  Deal  period,  and  later  a  field 
examiner  for  the  National  Labor  Relations  Board.  Subsequently  he  served  as 
conference  director  of  the  School  of  Public  and  International  Affairs  at  Princeton 


X  INTRODUCING  THE   TEAM 

University,  and  as  panel  secretary  to  the  National  Defense  Mediation  Board. 
During  World  War  II  he  was  associated  with  the  Administrative  Management 
and  Estimates  divisions  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Oifice  of  the 
President.  His  chief  work  is  Administrative  Regulation  (1942),  a  study  of  the 
methods  by  which  interest  groups  participate  in  the  administrative  process. 

Milton  M.  Mandcll  is  at  present  in  charge  of  testing  for  administrative  and 
managerial  positions,  a  significant  phase  of  the  program  of  the  United  States 
Civil  Service  Commission.  He  was  formerly  lecturer  in  personnel  administra- 
tion at  New  York  University  and  the  College  of  the  City  of  New  York.  He 
has  been  a  staff  member  of  the  municipal  civil  service  commission  in  Los  Angeles 
and  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority;  classification  consultant  to  the  State  of 
Connecticut;  personnel  officer  of  the  Materials  Division  of  the  War  Production 
Board;  and  chief  analyst  with  the  President's  Committee  for  Congested  Produc- 
tion Areas.  He  is  the  co-author  of  Education  and  the  Civil  Service  in  New 
Yor^  City  (1938),  product  of  a  study  of  public  personnel  administration  which 
he  supervised  under  auspices  of  New  York  University;  and  author  of  other 
contributions  to  public  personnel  administration. 

Harvey  C.  Mansfield  currently  serves  as  the  historian  of  the  Office  of  Price 
Administration.  He  was  formerly  assistant  professor  of  government  at  Yale 
University,  and  has  also  taught  at  Stanford  University.  He  was  a  member  of 
the  staff  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management.  In  1942 
he  joined  OPA  as  a  principal  administrative  officer,  and  subsequently  became  asso- 
ciate price  executive  and  price  executive  of  the  Consumer  Durable  Goods  Branch. 
In  1945  he  was  appointed  assistant  director  of  the  Consumer  Goods  Division  of 
OPA.  His  principal  publications  are  The  La^e  Cargo  Coal  Rate  Controversy 
(1932);  The  General  Accounting  Office  (1937),  one  of  the  special  studies  spon- 
sored by  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management;  and  The 
Comptroller  General  (1939). 

John  D.  Millett,  associate  professor  of  public  administration  at  Columbia 
University,  has  also  taught  at  Rutgers  University.  He  has  been  a  staff  member  of 
the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management;  assistant  secretary 
to  the  Committee  on  Public  Administration  of  the  Social  Science  Research  Coun- 
cil; and  special  assistant  to  the  Director  of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board. 
In  World  War  II  he  was  commissioned  a  major  in  the  United  States  Army,  as- 
signed to  the  Control  Division  at  headquarters  of  the  Army  Service  Forces;  he 
left  the  Army  as  a  colonel.  He  is  the  author  of  The  Worlds  Progress  Adminis- 
tration in  New  Yor^  City  (1938)  and  The  British  Unemployment  Assistance 
Board  (1939);  co-author  of  Federal  Administrators  (1939)  and  The  Adminis- 
tration of  Federal  Wor\  Relief  (1941).  One  of  his  latest  contributions  to  pro- 
fessional journals  is  a  study  of  the  direction  of  supply  activities  in  the  War 
Department,  published  in  the  American  Political  Science  Review,  April  and 
June,  1944. 

Fritz  Morstein  Marx,  a  research  fellow  of  the  Rockefeller  Foundation  in 
1930-1931,  has  taught  at  the  Pennsylvania  School  of  Social  Work,  Princeton 
University,  New  York  University,  Harvard  University,  Columbia  University, 
Queens  College,  Yale  University,  and  American  University.  Prior  to  his  enlist- 
ment in  the  Army  in  1942,  he  served  as  consultant  to  various  local,  state,  and 
federal  agencies.  He  has  been  engaged  in  research  work  for  the  Commission 
of  Inquiry  on  Public  Service  Personnel,  and  was  the  first  chairman  of  the  Special 
Committee  on  Comparative  Administration,  sponsored  by  the  Committee  on 


INTRODUCING  THE  TEAM  xi 

Public  Administration  of  the  Social  Science  Research  Council.  Since  his  return 
from  the  Army,  he  has  worked  in  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Office 
of  the  President,  where  he  is  currently  employed  as  staff  assistant  in  the  Office 
of  the  Director.  His  writings  include  a  study  of  judicial  review  under  the 
Weimar  Constitution  (1927);  Government  in  the  Third  Reich  (rev.  ed.,  1937); 
and  a  series  of  papers  on  comparative  administrative  law.  He  is  the  editor  of 
Public  Management  in  the  New  Democracy  (1940). 

Don  K.  Price,  a  Rhodes  scholar  in  1932,  is  associate  director  of  the  Public 
Administration  Clearing  House  and  lecturer  in  political  science  at  the  University 
of  Chicago.  He  has  served  as  a  staff  member  of  the  Federal  Home  Loan  Bank 
Board  and  the  Central  Housing  Committee.  More  recently  he  has  been  attached 
to  the  Administrative  Management  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Execu- 
tive Office  of  the  President.  During  World  War  II  he  was  a  lieutenant  in  the 
United  States  Coast  Guard  Reserve,  assigned  to  headquarters  in  Washington. 
He  is  co-author  of  City  Manager  Government  in  the  United  States  (1939),  a 
study  undertaken  for  the  Committee  on  Public  Administration  of  the  Social 
Science  Research  Council.  He  was  the  first  managing  editor  of  Public  Admin- 
istration Review,  to  which  he  contributed  a  spirited  exchange  with  Professor 
Harold  J.  Laski  on  the  respective  merits  of  presidential  and  cabinet  government. 

Henry  Reining,  Jr.,  assistant  to  the  executive  director  of  the  Port  of  New 
York  Authority,  previously  was  management  consultant  with  Rogers  &  Slade  in 
New  York  City,  where  he  specialized  in  programs  for  the  selection  of  prospec- 
tive executives.  Before  1945  he  served  for  ten  years  as  the  first  educational 
director  of  the  National  Institute  of  Public  Affairs  in  Washington,  D.  C.,  which 
has  been  singularly  successful  in  sponsoring  governmental  internship  programs 
for  college  graduates  of  high  promise,  and  more  recently  for  able  federal  em- 
ployees on  an  in-service  basis;  the  latter  program  is  now  being  conducted  by  the 
United  States  Civil  Service  Commission.  Before  assuming  this  position,  he 
was  a  faculty  member  of  Princeton  University  and  research  associate  of  the 
Princeton  Local  Government  Survey.  He  has  also  taught  at  George  Washington 
University,  American  University,  and  the  University  of  Southern  California,  an 
institution  that  has  pioneered  in  the  field  of  government-employee  training.  He 
has  been  consultant  to  several  federal  agencies,  and  also  to  the  National  De- 
partment of  Administration  of  the  Public  Service  (DASP)  in  Brazil.  He  is 
the  co-editor  of  Regulatory  Administration  (1943)  and  author  of  a  number  of 
articles  in  academic  reviews. 

Wallace  S.  Sayre,  personnel  director  of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration, 
has  recently  been  appointed  professor  of  administration  at  the  School  of  Business 
and  Public  Administration  of  Cornell  University.  He  was  formerly  a  member 
of  the  political  science  faculty  of  New  York  University.  In  1937  he  was  ap- 
pointed secretary  of  the  municipal  civil  service  commission  in  New  York  City, 
and  a  year  later  became  a  member  of  the  commission.  Early  in  1942  he  entered 
the  service  of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration  as  principal  consultant  to  the 
Personnel  Branch.  Soon  afterwards  he  was  made  assistant  director  of  the  Fuel 
Rationing  Division;  he  assumed  direction  of  OPA's  personnel  functions  in 
1944.  He  is  a  consulting  editor  of  the  New  York  Legislative  Service,  and  was 
a  member  of  the  group  that  drafted  the  Model  Civil  Service  Law.  His  writings 
have  been  devoted  to  various  aspects  of  American  government  and  politics,  in- 
cluding political  biography  and  the  role  of  the  public  service.  He  is  co-author 
of  Charter  Revision  for  the  City  of  New  Yor^  (1934)  and  Education  and  the 
Civil  Service  in  New  Yor%  City  (1938). 


Xll  INTRODUCING  THE   TEAM 

Donald  C.  Stone  is  assistant  director  in  charge  of  administrative  management 
in  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Office  of  the  President — a  position  he  has 
occupied  since  1939.  He  has  played  a  prominent  role  in  the  field  of  govern- 
mental research,  serving  successively  as  a  staff  member  of  the  Cincinnati  Bureau 
of  Governmental  Research;  assistant  director  for  the  Committee  on  Uniform 
Crime  Records  of  the  International  Association  of  Chiefs  of  Police;  staff  member 
of  the  Institute  of  Public  Administration  in  New  York  City;  director  of  research 
of  the  International  City  Managers  Association;  and  executive  director  of  the 
Public  Administration  Service  in  Chicago.  During  these  years  he  has  also 
worked  as  a  consultant  to  many  federal  agencies,  including  the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority  and  the  Social  Security  Board.  As  an  officer  of  the  Federal  Gov- 
ernment, he  has  attended  numerous  international  conferences,  both  as  a  member 
of  the  United  States  delegation  and  in  an  advisory  capacity.  Formerly  asso- 
ciated with  the  University  of  Chicago  and  Syracuse  University,  he  is  now  adjunct 
professor  of  public  administration  at  American  University.  He  is  the  author  of 
The  Management  of  Municipal  Public  Worths  (1939)  and  other  studies,  most 
of  which  have  appeared  in  professional  periodicals. 

John  A.  Vieg,  professor  of  government  and  chairman  of  his  department  at 
Pomona  College,  has  taught  at  various  institutions,  including  Iowa  State  College. 
He  was  research  associate  at  the  University  of  Chicago  from  1934  to  1937.  In 
1943  he  became  a  staff  member  of  the  Administrative  Management  Division  of 
the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  where  he  dealt 
principally  with  matters  of  international  administration.  While  on  the  faculty 
of  Iowa  State  College,  he  also  served  as  vice  chairman  of  the  city  plan  commission 
of  Ames,  and  as  vice  chairman  of  the  Story  County  Civilian  Defense  Council.  He 
has  written  The  Government  of  Education  in  Metropolitan  Chicago  (1939), 
and  is  co-author  of  City  Manager  Government  in  Seven  Cities  (1940),  The 
Future  of  Government  in  America  (1942),  and  Wartime  Government  in  Opera- 
tion (1943). 

Dwight  Waldo,  formerly  of  Yale  University,  is  a  member  of  the  political 
science  department  at  the  University  of  California  in  Berkeley.  In  1942  he 
became  a  staff  member  of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  serving  successively 
as  an  administrative  assistant,  assistant  economist,  anu  price  analyst.  In  1945 
he  transferred  to  the  Administrative  Management  Division  of  the  Bureau  of 
the  Budget,  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  where  he  devoted  his  time  prin- 
cipally to  organizational  studies.  His  published  writings,  thus  far  confined  to 
the  learned  reviews,  have  dealt  with  such  seemingly  disparate  matters  as  social 
thought  and  public-service  recruitment.  His  first  book,  an  analysis  of  the  theory 
of  American  public  administration,  is  scheduled  for  early  release. 


Contents 


CHAPTER  PACK 

PREFACE  vii 

INTRODUCING  THE  TEAM ix 


PARTI 
The  Role  of  Public  Administration 

1.  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION,  John  A.  Vieg       3 

1.  ADMINISTRATION — PUBLIC  AND  PRIVATE   3 

Administration  as  Part  of  All  Planned  Effort,  3;  Unity  of  Scientific  Knowledge 
of  Administration,  4;  Scope  of  Pub'ic  Admmistr  tion,  5;  Elements  of  Public 
Administration,  6;  Administration  as  Servant  of  Policy,  7. 

2.  THE  AMERICAN  BACKGROUND 9 

Heritage  from  Britain,  9;  Influence  of  the  Frontier,  11;  Hamiltoman  and  JefTer- 
soman  Traditions,  12;  Public  Administration  and  the  National  Economy,  13; 
Assertion  of  the  Public  Interest,  14. 

3.  THE  EXPANSION  OF  GOVERNMENTAL  FUNCTIONS  14 

American  Pragmatism,  14;  Limits  to  Government  Nonintervention,  15;  Estab- 
lishment of  Clientele  Departments,  16;  Rise  of  Governmental  Corporations,  17; 
Growth  of  Administrative  Activities,  18. 

4.  INCREASING  COMPETENCE  FOR  INCREASING  RESPONSIBILITIES 20 

Professional  Versus  Amateur,  20;  Patronage  and  Economy,  22;  Advances  in 
Structure  and  Procedure,  23;  Impact  of  Emergencies,  25;  Tasks  of  Admin- 
istration in  Mid-Century,  25. 

2.  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION,  Avcry  Leiserson      27 

£T"V-N 

1 .  THE  WORK  OF  THE  PIONEERS  >. .  .\ 27 

Beginnings  of  Administrative  Research,  27;  Wives  of  Governmental  Reform, 
28;  Organized  Dissemination  of  Knowledge,  25;  Role  of  Progressivism,  29;  Con- 
tribution of  the  Universities,  30. 

2.  THE  ADVANCEMENT  OF  KNOWLEDGE 31 

Relativity  of  Efficiency,  31;  Use  of  Outside  Experts,  32;  Challenge  to  Traditional 
Approach,  33;  Rise  of  Administrative  Self-Analysis,  34;  Reaffirmation  of  the 
Political  Context,  36. 

xiii 


XIV  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

3.  TRAINING  FOR  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  .......................       37 

Educational  Aspects,  37;  Contrast  with  Great  Britain,  39;  Post-Entry  Training, 
40;  Group  Structure  of  the  Public  Service,  41;  Higher  Career  Opportunities,  41. 

4.  THE  FRONTIERS  OF  RESEARCH  ................................       42 

Function  Versus  Structure,  42;  Man  in  Organization,  43;  Theory  of  Relation- 
ships, 44;  Progressive  Management,  46;  Horizons  of  Administrative  Research,  47. 

5.  ADMINISTRATION  —  ART  OR  SCIENCE?    .........................       48 

Aims  of  Scientific  Approach,  48;  Concerns  of  the  Technician,  49;  Science  and 
Social  Dynamics,  49;  Evaluated  Experimentation,  49;  Alliance  of  Theory  and 
Practice,  50. 

2*      UREAUCRACY—  FACT  AND  FICTION,  John  A.  Vteg  .........       51 

1.  SEMANTICS  AND  REALITIES  ...................................       51 

The  Language  of  Contempt,  51;  Officiousness  and  Frailty,  52;  Administrative 
Self-Promotion,  52;  Procedural  Rigmarole,  54;  Subjectivity  and  Objectivity,  55. 

2.  THE  SOURCES  OF  RED  TAPE  .................................       55 

Red  Tape  and  Green  Tape,  56;  Requirements  of  Efficiency,  56;  Predictability 
of  Performance,  57;  Government  of  Laws,  57;  Accountability  to  the  Public,  57. 

3.  THE  CHARGE  OF  DESPOTISM  .................................       58 

Effects  of  the  Industrial  Age,  58;  Charge  of  Usurpation,  59;  Legislative  Dele- 
gation, 60;  Flexibility  of  Statutory  Standards,  61;  Quasi-Judicial  Agencies,  61. 

4.  THE  BATTLE  AGAINST  REGIMENTATION   .......................       63 

Experience  Abroad,  63,  Parliamentary  Review  ot  Delegated  Legislation,  64; 
Ignoble  Partisanship,  65,  Matrix  of  a  Mixed  Economy,  65,  Experimental  Ac- 
commodation, 66. 

5.  THE  NEED  FOR  UNDERSTANDING   .............................       66 

Psychology  of  Public  Emplo\nunt,  67,  VYi!  of  Oliicial  Anonymity,  68;  Teams 
and  Cogs,  69;  Ethics  of  Political  Counsel,  70;  Fact  Over  Fiction,  70. 

4.    DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION,  Don   K.  Price   ...........       72 

1  .  LEGISLATIVE-EXECUTIVE  RELATIONSHIPS    .......................       ?2 

Prophets  of  111,  72,  Dangers  of  Oversimplification,  74;  Control  by  Delegation, 
75,  Democracy  and  Legislative  Supremacy,  76;  Legislators  Vc^us  Legisla- 
tures, 77. 

2.  THE  PUBLIC  AS  STAR  CUSTOMER  .............................       78 

Methods  of  Opinion  Analysis,  78;  Advisory  Committees,  79;  Day-by-Day 
Administrative  Relationships,  79;  Reporting  to  the  Public,  80;  Commissions  of 
Inquiry,  80. 


3.  PUBLIC  ^PARTICIPATION  ...................................... 

Cooperative  Government,  81;  Combined  Operations  Among  Levels  of  Gov- 
ernment, 82;  Benefits  of  Intergovernmental  Collaboration,  84;  Inclusion  of 
Business  and  Labor,  85;  Group  Initiative  Under  National  Standards,  86. 


CONTENTS  XV 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

4.  REPRESENTING  THE  PUBLIC  INTEREST 87 

Interdependence  of  Public  and  Private  Interests,  87;  Threefold  Collaboration  in 
Policy -Making,  88;  Informality  of  Policy-Making/  Process,  89;  Experimental 
Approach,  90;  General  Interest  Over  Special  Interest,  90. 

5.  DEPARTMENTAL  DEMOCRACY    91 

Individual  Freedom  Versus  Institutional  Restraint,  97;  Sense  of  General  Pur- 
pose, 93;  Vice  of  Departmentalism,  94;  Inroads  of  Perfectionism,  95;  Demo- 
cratic Self- Education,  96. 

5.  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION, 

Fritz  Morstein  Marx   98 

1.  THE  "AMERICAN  SYSTEM"  AND  THE  SERVICE  STATE 98 

Wartime  Rccurd,  98;  Peacetime  Relevance  of  Wartime  Achievement,  98;  Long- 
Range  Trend  Toward  the  Service  State,  99;  Assurance  Versus  Fear,  100;  Test 
of  the  Service  State,  100. 

2.  THE  NEEDS  OF  THE  SERVICE  STATE  101 

Making  Democracy  Succeed,  101;  Continuity  of  Progress,  102;  Surviving  Con- 
tradictions, 103;  Requirements  of  Public  Management,  104;  Requirements  of 
Policy  Planning,  105. 

3.  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION — INSTRUMENT  OF  GOVERNMENT 106 

Prominence  of  Public  Administration,  106;  Demands  on  Legislative  Leadership, 
106;  Role  of  the  Judicial  Power,  107;  Resources  of  Administration,  108;  Admin- 
istration as  a  Fitting  Process,  108. 

4.  THE  ENLISTMENT  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  JUDGMENT 108 

Legislative  Marching  Orders,  108;  Political  Feasibility  of  Policy,  709,  Admin- 
istrative Feasibility  of  Policy,  110.  Blending  of  Judgments,  110;  Administra- 
tive Freedom  of  Expression,  111. 

5.  THE  CONTRIBUTION  OF  SERVICE  Ill 

Popular  Basis  of  Administrative  Services,  111;  Habit  of  Self-Restraint,  112; 
Governmental  Reinforcement  of  the  Enterprise  Economy,  113,  Benefits  of  Regu- 
lation, 113;  Popular  Accountability  of  Administration,  114. 

6.  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION — SOCIAL  BUFFER 114 

Fountains  of  Administrative  Knowledge,  114,  Government's  Intelligence  Func- 
tion, 114;  Public  Research  and  Analysis,  115;  Getting  at  the  Facts,  116;  Con- 
cern for  the  Underdog,  776. 

PART  II 
Organization  and  Management 

6.  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION,  John  D.  Milieu 121 

1.  THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  PLANNING 121 

Essence  of  Planning,  727;  Contribution  of  Administrative  Planning,  123;  Plan- 
ning and  Legislation,  124;  Planning  and  Administration,  124;  Interrelation  of 
Planning  Activities,  124. 


XVi  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

2.  THE  MACHINERY  FOR  PLANNING 126 

Federal  Improvisation,  126;  Natural  Resources  Planning  Board,  727;  Office  of 
War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion,  128;  New  York  City  Planning  Commis- 
sion, 128;  Departmental  Planning  Units,  130. 

3.  PLANNING  VERSUS  OPERATIONS  130 

Opportunities  for  Conflict,  1 30;  Task  of  Progressive  Management,  131;  Plan- 
ners as  Administrators,  131,  Practical  Test  of  Planning,  132;  Planning  Through 
Action  Agencies,  133. 

4.  THE  REQUIREMENTS  OF  PLANNING  133 

Long-Range  Versus  Short-Range  Planning,  133;  Planning  Personnel,  134;  Plan- 
ning Techniques,  136,  Public  Relations  of  Planning,  138;  Summary,  138. 

WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION,  John  D.  Milieu. .     140 

1.  THE  ARCHITECTURE  OF  ORGANIZATION   140  - 

Terminology,  140.  Bases  of  Organization,  HI;  Choice  of  Basis,  H2;  Dynamics 
and  Rigidities,  H3;  Political  Factors  in  Organization,  144. 

2.  LINE  AND  STAFF  (1 4y 

''Meaning  of  Line,  H5;  Meaning  of  Staff,  146;  Staff  Activities  Inherent  in  Ad- 
ministration, 147;  Ceritral  Service  Activities,  147;  Functional  and  Operating 
Staff,  147. 

3.  QUEST  OF  ORGANIZATIONAL  UNITY 148 

Hierarchy  and  Span  of  Control,  148;  Decentralization,  149;  Unity  of  Com- 
mand, 150;  Coordination,  752;  Integration,  752. 

4.  GUIDING  RULES  OF  ORGANIZATIONAL  DESIGN  153 

Need  for  Standards  of  Organization,  153;  Insuring  Sound  Organization,  154; 
Summary,  756. 

fi.    THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE,  John  A.  Vieg 158 

1.  DUAL  FUNCTION:    POLICY  AND  ADMINISTRATION  

Means  and  Ends,  158;  Separation  of  Political  Leadership  and  Administration, 
759;  Combination  of  Political  Leadership  and  Administration,  767. 

r2.  LEADERSHIP  AND  AUTHORITY 162 

Cloak  of  Legal  Power,  762;  Personal  Qual  fications,  762;  Mark  of  Leadership, 
164;  Political  and  Administrative  Talent,  765;  American  Presidents,  l£6;  Crea- 
tive  Policy   Versus   Sound   Administration,    767;   Business   Leaders, 
ernors  and  Mayors,  168. 

3.  EXTERNAL  RELATIONSHIPS  169 

Relations  with  the  Judiciary,  769;  Relations  with  the  Legislature,  170;  Agency 
Contacts  with  Legislators,  777;  Relations  with  Other  Chief  Executives,  777; 
Relations  with  Political  Parties,  772;  Puolic  Opinion  and  Interest  Groups,  772. 

4.  INTERNAL  DIRECTION  AND  CONTROL 174 

Administrative  Planning  and  Direction,  774;  Executive  Coordination  and  Ad- 
ministrative Reporting,  174;  Constitutional  Supports,  775;  Statutory  Implemen- 
tation, 777. 


CONTENTS  XVii 

CHAPTER  PACE 

5.  ARMS  OF  MODERN  MANAGEMENT 178 

Need  for  Assistance  to  the  President,  178;  Realigning  the  Executive  Branch, 
779;  Central  Staff  Facilities,  180;  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  181;  Policy 
Coordination,  182;  Potentialities  of  the  Cabinet,  182. 

9.    THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM,  Fritz  Morstein  Marx 184 

1.  GENERAL  FEATURES   184 

Purpose  of  Departmentalization,  184;  Structure  of  Departmental  System,  185; 
Factors  in  Departmentalization,  187;  Undirected  Growth,  189;  Quasi-Depart- 
mcnts,  190. 

2.  INTERDEPARTMENTAL  COORDINATION   191 

Staff  Establishments,  792;  Coordinating  Agencies,  193;  Role  of  the  Cabinet, 
195;  Use  of  Interdepartmental  Committees,  196;  Avenues  of  Progress,  797. 

3.  THE  SECRETARY'S  BUSINESS 198 

External  Affairs,  198;  Living  in  a  Goldfish  Bowl,  799;  Character  of  Execu- 
tive Function,  200;  Classes  of  Executive  Aides,  201;  Attaining  an  Institutional 
Product,  201. 

4.  THE  BUREAU  PATTERN   202 

Special  Concerns  Versus  General  Purpose,  202;  Centrifugal  Pull,  203;  Bureau 
Intransigence,  204,  Weight  of  Professionalization  on  Bureau  Level,  204;  Re- 
affirming Unity  of  Purpose,  205. 

10.    INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS,  James  W. 

Fesler 207 

1.  TYPES  OF  INDEPENDENT  ESTABLISHMENTS 207 

Meaning  of  Independence,  207;  Institutional  Safeguards  of  Independence,  209; 
Appointment  and  Removal  of  Members,  210;  Financial  Support  and  Basic  Au- 
thority, 277;  Political  Factors,  271. 

2.  NATURE  AND  CONDUCT  OF  REGULATORY  BUSINESS 212 

Rule-Making  and  Case -by-Case  Decision,  2/2;  Administrative  Approach,  274; 
Mixture  of  Approaches,  275;  Judicial  Control,  277;  Proposals  of  Attorney  Gen- 
eral's Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure,  279. 

3.  THE  RECORD  OF  INDEPENDENCE 221 

Regulation  by  Independent  Commissions  and  by  Executive  Departments,  227; 
Clifcntcle  Departments  and  Directive  Power,  222;  Struggle  for  Control  Over 
Independent  Commissions,  22.?;  Humphrey  Case,  224;  Experience  in  the  States, 
226. 

4.  THE  PRICE  OF  INDEPENDENCE 227 

Popular  Illusions,  227;  Need  for  Policy  Coordination,  228;  Lethargy  of  Inde- 
pendence, 228;  Pressure  for  Reform,  229;  Lack  of  Stimulation,  229. 

5.  ORGANIZATIONAL  ALTERNATIVES 230 

Executive  Control,  231;  Legislative  Control,  231;  Judicial  Control,  232;  Segre- 
gation of  Powers  of  Independent  Commissions,  233;  Proposals  of  President's 
Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  234. 


XVlii  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

11.  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS,  V.  O.  Key,  Jr 236 

1.  CENTRAL  CONTROLS  AND  MANAGERIAL  FREEDOM 236 

Direction  by  the  Chief  Executive,  236;  Overhead  Control  of  Departmental 
Methods,  236,  Control  Machinery  in  Action,  237;  Central  Control  and  De- 
partmental Resourcefulness,  238;  Changing  Role  of  Government  Corporations, 
238. 

2.  THE  DEVELOPMENT  OF  THE  CORPORATE  SYSTEM  IN  GOVERNMENT.  .     240 

Variety  of  Government  Corporations,  240;  Government  Corporations  as  Product 
of  Emergencies,  241;  Great  Depression  and  World  War  II,  241,  Government 
Corporations  m  the  Field  of  Farm  Credit,  243,  Scope  of  Corporate  System,  244. 

3.  OVERHEAD  CONTROL  OF  CORPORATE  OPERATIONS 244 

Immunit)  from  the  Power  of  the  Purst,  244;  Restrictions  on  Corporate  Auton- 
omy, 246,  Emerging  State  of  Budgetary  Control,  250,  Powers  of  Comptroller 
General,  257;  Central  Control  of  Personnel,  255. 

4.  CORPORATE  AUTONOMY  AND  POLITICAL  RESPONSIBILITY 256 

Legislative  Bewilderment,  256,  Political  A  iMgomsms,  258,  Providing  Informa- 
tion for  the  Legislature,  259,  Enforcing  Political  Responsibility  of  Government 
Corporations,  260,  Contribution  of  the  Corporate  Device,  262. 

12.  FIELD  ORGANIZATION,  James  W.  Fesler 264 

1.  THE  GROWTH  OF  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 264 

Continental  Prototypes,  264;  British  Development,  266;  Expansion  of  Federal 
Functions,  266,  Technological  Progress,  267;  Scope  of  Field  Organization, 
265. 

»2J  CENTRALIZATION  AND  DECENTRALIZATION 269 

Approach  to  Decentralization,  269;  Factor  of  Responsibility,  270;  Administra- 
tive Factors,  270;  Functional  Factors,  273,  hxternal  Factors,  274. 
/ 

3.  FIELD-HEADQUARTERS  RELAT  IONS  276 

Rivalry  of  Functional  Experts  and  General  Administrators,  276;  Lines  of  Com- 
mand, 277;  Personnel  Policies,  279,  Headquarters  Office  of  Field  Operations, 
280,  Problems  of  Communication,  280;  Controls  Over  Field  Organization,  281; 
Problems  of  Multilevel  Field  Organization,  283. 

4.  INTERAGENCY  COORDINATION  IN  THE  FIELD 284 

Divergencies  in  Field  Organization,  284;  Emerging  Uniformities,  285;  Pooling 
of  Field  Resources,  286;  Regional  Coordinators,  287;  Special  Coordinative  Ma- 
chinery, 288. 

5.  THE  PROSPECTS  OF  JOINT  FIELD  PLANNING 289 

Regional  Planning  Commissions,  259,  Regional  Development  Authorities,  290; 
Function  Versus  Area,  297;  Remaining  Issues,  297;  Community-Level  Analysis, 
292. 

13.    INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION,  Harvey  C.  Mansfield  and  Fritz 

Morstein  Marx 294 


CONTENTS 

CHAPTER 

[My  FORMAL  AND  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 294 

Organic  Growth  of  Informal   Organization,  294;  Charts  and  Realities,  294;          " 
Attitudes  and  Motivations,  295;  Basis  of  Personal  Organization,  296;  Growing 
and  Shrinking  Organizations,  297. 

2.  ELEMENTS  OF  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 297 

Characteristic  Factors,  297;  Self -Expression  of  Influence,  297;  Variables  Affecting 
Authority,  299;  Forms  of  Personal  Organization,  300;  Ties  of  Allegiance,  303. 

3.  NONHIERARCHICAL  SOURCES  OF  POWER 306 

Men  Behind  the  Throne,  307;  The  Personal  Secretary,  309;  The  Invincible 
Constellation,  311;  Clubs  and  Clusters,  312;  Voice  of  the  Union,  313. 

14.  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION,  Avcry  Leiscrson. ..     314 

1.  THE  MEANING  OF  INTEREST  REPRESENTATION 314 

Types  of  Interest  Groups,  314;  Interest  Orientation  of  Public  Administration, 
315;  Governmentahzation  of  Interest  Groups,  316;  Interest  Groups  and  Class 
Theory,  317 ;  Demands  for  Interest  Representation,  317. 

2.  CLIENTELE  ORGANIZATION 318 

Growth  of  Clientele  Agencies,  318,  Disadvantages  of  Clientele  Organization, 
318,  Attempts  at  Internal  Balance  of  Interests,  319;  Functions  of  Clientele 
Agencies,  320;  Experiences  of  the  Great  Depression  and  World  War  II,  321. 

3.  STAFFING  FOR  POINT  OF  VIEW 322 

Grounds  for  Interest  Representation,  322;  Administrative  Appointment  of  Inter- 
est Representatives,  323;  Problems  of  Dual  Allegiance,  324;  Group  Representa- 
tion Through  Special  Staff  Units,  326,  Balance  Sheet  of  Experience,  329. 

4.  INTEREST  REPRESENTATION  ON  ADMINISTRATIVE  BOARDS 330 

Membership  Requirements,  330;  Nomination  by  Interest  Groups,  331;  Bipar- 
tisan and  Tripartite  Boards,  332,  Record  of  Wartime  Labor  Boards,  333;  Test 
of  Interest  Compromise,  334. 

5.  THE  PRINCIPLE  OF  CONSULTATION 334 

General  Theory  of  Interest  Representation,  334;  Basic  Distinctions  in  Group 
Representation,  335;  Organization  of  Interest  Participation,  336;  Three  War- 
time Examples,  336;  Foundations  of  Interest  Consultation,  338. 

15.  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL,  V.  O.  Key,  Jr 339 

0 1.  MEANS  AND  CONDITIONS  OF  CONTROL 339 

Central  Issue  of  Governance,  339;  Formal  Means  of  Legislative  Control,  340; 
Looking  Into  Particulars,  341;  Atomization  of  Control,  342;  Weakness  of  Leg- 
islative Discipline,  343. 

2.  CONTRADICTION  OF  INTEGRATION  344 

Absence  of  Collective  Administrative  Responsibility,  344;  Splintering  Effects  of 
Legislative-Executive  Relations,  345;  Legislative  Dealings  with  Subordinate 
Personnel,  346;  Subtler  Legislative  Influences,  347;  Grants  of  Organizational 
Independence,  348. 


XX  *  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

3.  DIFFUSION  OF  INITIATIVE  AND  RESPONSIBILITY 349 

Executive  Share  in  Policy-Making,  349;  Desertions  from  the  President's  Pro- 
gram, 350;  Inadequate  Legislation,  351;  Incongruity  Between  Power  and  Re- 
sponsibility, 352;  Legislators  and  Administrators,  352. 

4.  QUEST  FOR  ACCOUNTABILITY 354 

Selecting  Department  Heads,  354;  Lower-Level  Appointments,  355;  Attempted 
Extension  of  Senatorial  Confirmation,  356;  Removal  Power,  357;  Legislative 
Pressure  for  Resignation,  358. 

5.  DRIVES  TOWARD  REFORM  358 

Case  for  Cabinet  Government,  359,  Merits  of  a  Question  Period,  359;  Legis- 
lative Committee  Meetings  with  Administrators,  360;  Legislative  Staffs,  360; 
Making  Legislative  Work  Manageable,  361. 


PART  III 
Working  Methods 

16.  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY,  Avery 

Leiserson  365 

1.  POLICY  FORMATION  AND  POLICY  SANCTION 365 

Realm  of  Administrative  Policy,  365;  Breadth  of  Policy-Making  Process,  365; 
Prompting  Role  of  Management,  366;  Legislative  Basis  of  Administrative  Policy, 
366,  Main  Division  of  Responsibility,  367;  Coordinate  Tasks  of  Legist  a  tuic 
and  Chief  Executive,  368. 

2.  FACT-FINDING  AND  DISCRETION  IN  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 368 

Delegation  of  Policy  Determination,  368;  Administrative  Contacts  with  Pri- 
vate Fact-Finding  Groups,  369;  Interagency  Use  of  Staff  Resources,  370;  Govern- 
ment-wide Clearance  of  Policy  Proposals,  370;  Insuring  Objectivity  in  Staff 
Recommendations,  371. 

3.  IDEOLOGY  AND  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 373 

Sources  of  Ideology,  373;  Ideology  of  Political  Office,  373;  Administrative 
Ideology,  374;  Intellectual  Flexibility  and  Emotional  Stability,  374;  Effects 
of  Ideological  Orientation,  375. 

4.  EXTERNAL  INFLUENCES  AND  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 375 

Impact  of  Interest  Groups,  375;  Public  Relations,  376;  Issues  of  Legality,  376; 
Task  of  the  Agency  Lawyer,  377;  Dynamics  of  Administrative  Policy-Makmg, 
377. 

17.  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE,  Dwight  Waldo 381 

1.  THE  NATURE  AND  LIMITATIONS  OF  PROCEDURE , 381 

Meaning  of  Procedure,  381;  Role  of  Procedure,  381;  Procedures  as  Laws  of 
Activity,  382;  Procedure  as  Physiology  of  Organization,  383;  Procedure  as  In- 
stitutional Habit,  383. 


CONTENTS  XXI 

CHAPTER  pAGE 

2.  PROCEDURES  AND  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 385 

Rule  of  Law,  385;  Safeguarding  Liberty  and  Equality,  386;  Legislative  Prescrip- 
tion of  Procedure,  386;  Protecting  Administrative  Morality,  387;  Aims  of  Pro- 
cedure, 388. 

3.  TYPES  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  PROCEDURES  388 

Classes  of  Procedures,  388;  Institutional  Procedures,  389;  Working  Procedures, 
389;  Diversity  of  Procedures,  391;  Two  Illustrations,  39 L 

4.  CREATION  AND  CRITERIA  392 

Procedure-Making  Compared  with  Pohcy-Making,  392;  Procedure-Making  Units, 
394;  Art  of  Making  Procedures,  394;  Work  Simplification  and  Procedural  Stand- 
ardization, 395;  Problems  of  Procedure-Making,  396. 

5.  How  TO  LIVE  AMONG  PROCEDURES 398 

Law  Versus  Dispatch,  398,  Deficient  Procedures,  399;  Assessing  Red  Tape,  399. 

18.  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT,  Fritz  Morstein  Marx 

and  Henry  Reining,  Jr 400 

1.  THE  DUAL  FUNCTION  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 400 

Importance  of  Intermediate  Points  of  Control,  400;  Middle  Management — Step- 
child of  Administrative  Research,  401;  Recognition  of  a  Higher  Line  Career, 
402;  Middle  Management  and  Top  Direction,  404;  Middle  Management  and 
Control  of  Operations,  406. 

2.  SUPPORTING  TOP  DIRECTION 408 

Effectiveness  of  Downward  Communication,  408',  Two-Way  Traffic  of  Thought, 
411;  Taking  Orders,  413;  Tabulations  of  the  Operator,  414;  Thinking  in  Larger 
Terms,  415. 

3.  RUNNING  THE  SHOW 416 

Problems  of  Delegation,  416;  Reinforcing  the  Line  Sector,  417;  Organizing  for 
Work,  418;  Reporting  Schemes,  419;  Keeping  Record,  420. 

19.  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION,  Henry  Reining.  Jr 421 

1.  WHAT  is  SUPERVISION ?   42P 

Direction  With  Authority,  421;  Concept  of  Functional  Foreman,  421;  Phases  of 
Supervision,  422;  Scope  of  Supervision,  422;  Institutional  Aspects,  42 3. 

2:  THE  SUPERVISORY  SKILLS  424 

Wartime  Innovations,  424;  Job  Instruction,  426;  Improving  Methods,  428; 
Working  With  People,  430;  Work  Simplification,  432. 

'  3.  PROBLEMS  OF  SUPERVISION   434 

Variations  in  Supervisory  Situation,  434;  Requirements  of  Good  Supervision, 
435;  Democracy  of  Work,  437;  Selecting  Supervisors,  439;  Supervision  and  Pol- 
icy, 441;  Span  of  Supervision,  442;  Employee  Organization  and  Supervision, 
442;  Short-Run  Versus  Long-Run  Point  of  View,  443. 

4.  SUPERVISION  AND  EMPLOYEE  INITIATIVE 444 

Institutional  Climate,  444;  Top  Management  Support,  445;  Channeling  Em- 
ployee Initiative,  445;  Suggestion  Systems,  445;  Rating  Employees,  446. 


XX11  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

20.  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT,  Donald  C.  Stone...    448 

1.  EVOLUTIONARY  CURRENTS  448 

Beginnings  ot  the  Analytical  Approach,  448;  Growth  of  Systematic  Inquiry, 
449;  Academic  and  Professional  Support,  449;  Stimulus  from  Private  Manage- 
ment, 450;  Government  Response,  452. 

2.  ORGANIZATION  FOR  ADMINISTRATIVE  ANALYSIS  452 

Conceivable  Alternatives,  452;  Improvement  Through  the  Administrator's  Per- 
sonal Action,  453;  Use  of  Outside  Consultants,  453;  Use  ot  Committees,  454; 
Staff  Meetings,  455;  Role  of  an  Administrative  General  Staff,  456;  Types  of  Ad- 
ministrative Planning  Offices,  459;  Tasks  of  Line  Operators  and  Supervisors, 
461;  Role  of  the  Rank  and  File,  462. 

3.  TECHNIQUES  FOR  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT / . . .     462 

Mission  of  the  Administrator,  462;  Types  of  Administrative  Surveys,  464; 
Reconnaissance,  466;  Planning  the  Survey,  466;  Review  of  Written  Materials, 
467;  Questionnaires  and  Check  Lists,  468;  Interviews,  469;  Observation  of  Opera- 
tions, 470;  Review  of  Communications,  471;  Work-Load  and  Work-Measure- 
ment Data,  471;  Charting  Devices,  472;  Reports,  472. 

4.  BASIC  RESOURCES  IN  MANAGEMENT  IMPROVEMENT 473 

Qualifications  for  Analysis,  473;  Skill  in  Human  Relations,  474;  Training  Sur- 
veys, 475;  Employee-Initiated  Action,  476;  Summary,  476. 

21.  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE,  Wallace  S.  Sayre 479 

1.  THE  MEANING  OF  MORALE 479 

Components  of  Morale,  479;  True  Com  and  Counterfeit,  480;  Democratic  Im- 
plications of  Morale,  481;  Doctrinal  Counterinfluences,  481;  Impact  of  Military 
and  Business  Prototypes,  483. 

2.  BUILDING  GROUP  MORALE   483  ] 

Basic    Premises,    483;    New    Methodology,   484;   Teamwork,   485;   Leadership, 

485;  Group  Development,  486;  Working  Together,  487;  Union  Attitudes, 
488;  Incentives,  490 \  Performance  Standards,  490;  Essentiality  of  Purpose,  491. 

3.  THE  MODES  OF  DISCIPLINE 491 

Aims  of  Discipline,  491;  Disciplinary  Restraints,  492;  Political  Aspects,  493; 
Service  Ethics,  493;  Evocation  of  Self-Discipline,  494. 

4.  MORALE  AND  INSTITUTIONAL  PATTERN 495 

Organizational  Structure  and  Concerted  Action,  495;  Balance  of  Structure  and 
Morale,  495;  Organization  in  Action,  495;  Effects  of  Specialization,  496;  Dis- 
cipline as  Affirmative  Pressure,  496. 


PART  IV 
Responsibility  and  Accountability 

22,    ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY,  George  A.  Graham 501 

1.  MEN  AND  INSTITUTIONS 501 

Responsible  Men,  501;  Responsible  Institutions,  503;  Interdependence  of  Men 
and  Institutions,  503;  The  Political  Implications  of  Business  Practice,  504; 
Automatism?  506* 


CONTENTS  XXiii 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

2.  LEGISLATIVE  RESPONSIBILITY 507 

Responsible  Legislators,  507;  Realism  in  Responsibility  of  Legislators,  507;  Leg- 
islative Irresponsibility?  508;  Suicidal  Tendencies,  509;  Responsibility  and  Lead- 
ership, 509;  Responsibility  of  the  Legislative  Body,  510. 

3.  EXECUTIVE  RESPONSIBILITY  512 

Elected  Chief  Executives,  512;  Responsibility  of  the  Chief  Executive,  51 3\  Ex- 
ecutive Restraint,  514;  Executive  Emphasis  on  Teamwork,  514;  High  Officials — 
Political  Leadership,  515. 

4.  ADMINISTRATIVE  IMPLICATIONS 516 

Politician  and  Civil  Servant,  576;  General  Interest  Versus  Special  Interest,  576; 
Integrity  and  Good  Faith,  577;  Civil  Service — But  Not  Servility,  577. 

23.  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST,  Don  K.  Price 519 

1.  THE  RULE  OF  PRACTICALITY 519 

Propriety  of  Administrative  Rule-Making  and  Adjudication,  579;  Test  of  Social 
Utility,  520;  Two  Illustrations,  527;  Extending  the  Rule  of  Law,  522;  Admin- 
istrative Regulation  as  Alternative  to  Public  Ownership,  522. 

2.  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  PROCESS  AND  THE  LAWYERS 523 

Prevention  Over  Punishment,  523;  Regulation  as  Partnership  in  Management, 
524;  Informal  Settlement  Versus  Formal  Adjudication,  525;  Balance  of  Public 
Interests,  526;  "Snuffing  the  Approach  of  Tyranny,"  527;  Federal  Administra- 
tive Procedure  Act,  529. 

3.  ADMINISTRATIVE  FAIRNESS  AND  JUDICIAL  REVIEW 531 

Rules  of  Evidence,  531;  Spot-Check  of  Judicial  Review,  532;  Scope  of  Judicial 
Review,  533;  Legitimate  Judicial  Concerns,  534;  Legislative  and  Judicial  Stand- 
ards of  Review,  535. 

4.  THE  ORGANIZATION  OF  ADJUDICATION 537 

Prosecutor-and-Judge  Agencies,  537;  Continental  Administrative  Courts,  538; 
American  Alternatives,  539;  Executive  Integration  of  Regulatory  Bodies,  540; 
Political  Factors,  542. 

5.  CONCLUSION 543 

Benefits  of  Administrative  Specialization,  543;  Combining  Flexibility  and  Prin- 
ciple, 543. 

24.  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS,  Milton  M.  Manddl 544 

1.  RESPONSIBILITY  AND  COMPETENCE    544 

Ensuring  Responsive  and  Resourceful  Administration,  544;  Management  and 
the  Personnel  Function,  544;  Reformist  Background  and  Legislative  Aspirations, 
545;  New  Outlook,  5-46;  Diversity  ot  Government  Employment,  546. 

2.  THE  PERSONNEL  OFFICE  IN  GOVERNMENT 547 

Central  Personnel  Agencies,  548;  Working  Relationships,  549;  Departmental 
Personnel  Offices,  550;  Relations  With  Operating  Officials,  551;  Qualifications 
for  Personnel  Work,  552. 


XXIV  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  PAGE 

3.  CLASSIFICATION  AND  COMPENSATION 553 

Characteristics  of  Classification,  553 \  Keeping  Classification  Up-To-Date,  554; 
General  Overview  Versus  Special  Considerations,  554;  Classification  and  the 
Career  Service,  555;  Compensation,  556. 

4.  EMPLOYMENT 557 

Implications  of  the  Career  Idea,  557;  Recruitment,  559;  Examinations,  560; 
Written  Tests,  562;  Oral  Tests,  56J;  Evaluation  of  Education  and  Experience, 
564;  Performance  Tests,  565;  Placement,  566, 

5.  TRAINING  567 

Types  of  Training,  567;  Prc-Entry  Training,  568;  Orientation,  570;  In-Scrvicc 
Training,  57f ,  Post-Entry  Training,  57 3. 

6.  EMPLOYEE  RELATIONS 574 

Place  of  the  Union,  574;  Stress  and  Strain,  574;  Unionism  and  Service  Neu- 
trality, 575;  Value  of  Unions  to  Management,  575;  Grievance  Procedure,  576. 

25.    FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY,  Harvey  C.  Mansfield 577 

1.  FUEL  FOR  THE  ENGINES  OF  ADMINISTRATION 577 

Administrative  Responsibility  and  Fiscal  Accountability,  577;  Multitude  of 
Voices  578;  Pressures  and  Restraints,  579;  Pattern  of  Legislative  Money  Grants, 
580;  Forms  of  Accountability,  58 L 

2.  JUSTIFICATION    582 

Call  for  Estimates,  582;  Departmental  Consideration,  583;  Formulation  of  the 
Executive  Budget,  586;  Legislative  Action,  557;  Congressional  Reform  Pro- 
posals, 590. 

3.  BUDGETARY  COORDINATION 593 

Essence  of  Coordination,  593;  Stimulation  of  Program  Thinking,  594;  Coordi- 
nation by  Consultation,  595;  Departmental  Synthesis,  596;  Top-Level  Coordi- 
nation, 597. 

4.  BUDGET  EXECUTION  598 

Budget  Principles  and  the  Test  of  Practice,  598;  Divergence  Over  Ultimate  Ends, 
602;  Fund  Control,  603;  Allotments,  60 3;  Apportionments,  604;  Financial 
Reporting,  605;  Personnel  Ceilings,  605. 

5.  AUDIT  606 

Public  Finance  and  Representative  Government,  606;  Expenditure  Control  in 
England,  606;  Beginnings  of  Expenditure  Control  in  the  United  States,  607; 
Specificity  of  Appropriations,  608;  Administrative  Checks,  609;  Delay  and  Lax- 
ity, 610;  Path  of  Reform,  672;  Formation  of  the  General  Accounting  Office, 
613;  Control  Versus  Audit,  614;  Safeguarding  Operational  Responsibility,  6/5; 
Balance  Sheet  of  Audit  and  Settlement  of  Accounts,  6/7. 

INDEX 623 


Parti 
THE  ROLE  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 


CHAPTER 


The  Growth  of  Public  Administration 

1.  ADMINISTRATION — PUBLIC  AND  PRIVATE 

Administration  as  Part  of  All  Planned  Effort.  Save  for  those  who  drift 
through  life  and  care  not  where  the  current  takes  them,  all  men  know 
something  from  their  own  experience  about  the  importance  and  the  ways 
of  administering  their  affairs.  For  to  refuse  to  let  circumstances  run  some 
wayward  course  and  to  work  instead  within  the  limits  they  impose  to 
attain  a  more  acceptable  end — this,  at  heart,  is  the  idea  of  administration. 

In  simplest  terms,  administration  is  determined  action  taken  in  pursuit 
of  conscious  purpose.  It  is  the  systematic  ordering  of  affairs  and  the  calcu- 
lated use  of  resources,  aimed  at  making  those  things  happen  which  we 
want  to  happen  and  simultaneously  preventing  developments  that  fail  to 
square  with  our  intentions,  (it  is  the  marshaling  of  available  labor  and 
materials  in  order  to  gain  that  which  is  desired  at  the  lowest  cost  in  energy, 
time,  and  money.)  No  man,  therefore,  who  singly  or  in  company  with 
others  has  ever  laid  out — or  had  laid  out  for  him — a  course  of  action  and 
proceeded  on  it  can  be  without  some  intimation  of  the  nature  of  adminis- 
tration. Motivated  by  their  desires  and  interests,  individuals  and  groups  of 
individuals  set  themselves  their  main  goals;  what  they  do  thereafter  to 
translate  these  goals  into  positive  achievement  is  essentially  administration. 

Regardless  of  the  field  of  human  endeavor,  there  is  thus  an  adminis- 
trative side  to  all  planned  effort.  In  simple  situations  where  the  things 
that  need  to  be  done  are  obvious,  and  it  is  fairly  plain  who  can  best  do 
what,  it  is  possible  for  people  sharing  an  objective  to  work  as  a  team  and 
never  grow  aware  of  the  fact  that  their  teamwork  for  the  common  purpose 
spells  administration.  But  when  conditions  become  complex  or  difficult, 
when  it  is  no  longer  easy  to  know  how  to  proceed  or  whether  the  resources 
available  will  be  adequate  for  gaining  the  common  end,  the  administrative 
aspect  emerges  as  a  matter  of  special  attention. 

This  conscious  concern  with  administration  arises  first,  and  principally, 
among  the  comparative  few  to  whom  it  falls  to  outline  programs,  devise 


4  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

procedures,  and  direct  or  supervise  operations.  In  a  more  general  way,  the 
importance  of  administration  also  comes  tcy  be  recognized  by  the  many — 
those  through  whom  the  process  of  cooperative  effort  operates,  so  to  speak— 
and  how  they  "see"  it  will  usually  make  a  considerable  difference  in  the 
success  or  failure  of  the  enterprise.  Where  they  share  in  its  purpose  and 
can  look  forward  to  sharing  in  some  way  in  its  fruits,  administration  is 
accepted  as  the  means  whereby  they  are  enabled  to  be  successful  in  their 
jobs,  and  they  work  accordingly.  Where  they  reject  the  purpose  and  see 
no  prospect  of  a  fair  participation  in  its  results,  administration  is  regarded 
as  a  means  of  exploiting  them  against  their  will — and  under  such  circum- 
stances even  a  genius  in  management  will  be  unable  to  achieve  more  than 
poor  results. 

Although  the  purpose-minded  individual  has  administrative  problems 
in  his  own  life,  whether  he  lives  in  the  modern  metropolis  or  on  a  farm 
in  Kansas,  we  usually  speak  of  administration  and  management  in  con- 
nection with  the  organization  and  direction  of  cooperative  or  collective 
activity.  The  two  terms — administration  and  management — are  sometimes 
used  interchangeably.  In  general,  administration  is  the  broader  term,  em- 
bracing such  factors  as  establishing  priority  of  specific  goals,  devising  the 
most  appropriate  structural  form  for  the  cooperative  enterprise,  and  harness- 
ing the  total  effort  toward  attainment  of  the  defined  ends.  Management, 
in  its  distinctive  sense,  relates  primarily  to  those  activities  which  are  designed 
to  make  the  enterprise  succeed  within  the  framework  of  policy,  structure, 
and  resources. 

Unity  of  Scientific  Knowledge  of  Administration.  It  is  in  the  sphere 
of  cooperative  or  collective  effort  that  administration  has  its  primary  signifi- 
cance. Whether  social,  religious,  economic,  or  political  in  character,  every 
organization  depends  on  administration  for  accomplishing  its  aims.  And 
the  larger  the  organization,  other  things  being  equal,  the  greater  the  need 
for  administration  to  be  formally  and  extensively  developed.  On  the  ques- 
tion of  whether  administration  is  chiefly  art  or  science^  we  can  here  confine 
ourselves  to  the  observation  that,  while  it  is  and  must  be  both;  it  is  steadily 
coming  to  be  more  than  an  art.  From  either  angle,  however,  it  is  equally 
obvious  that  the  precepts  and  standards  of  administration  comprise  a  single 
discipline.  Its  rules  and  insights  are  utilized  in  numerous  and  widely 
different  fields;  they  nevertheless  constitute  but  one  body  of  theory  and 
practice. 

Like  other  sciences,  the  developing  science  of  administration  has  many 
branches.  All  of  them,  however,  stem  from  the  same  trunk.  Not  a  few 
people  have  deluded  themselves  by  assuming — to  take  the  most  serious 
misconception — that  business  administration  and  government  administration 
are  entirely  separate  spheres,  completely  distinct  from  each  other.  The 
fact  is  that  they  have  more  in  common  than  not.  Neither  stands  alone; 
both  are  parts  of  a  larger  whole.  As  disciplines  they  differ  not  so  much 


THE  GROWTH  OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  5 

in  theory  and  practice  as  in  the  uses  to  which  they  are  put.  Yet  even  in 
their  particular  objectives  the  gap  between  them  is  not  as  wide  as  some 
seem  to  suppose.  Government  and  business  profit  alike  by  contributions 
made  by  either  to  the  advancement  of  administration.  As  one  example,  the 
growing  membership  and  influence  of  the  Society  for  the  Advancement  of 
Management,  supported  by  both  groups,  prove  that  these  truths  are  being 
appreciated  on  both  sides.  Both  are  realizing  how  much  theirs  is  a  common 
goal  and  a  common  interest. 

Business  affords  the  most  obvious  illustration  of  private  administration. 
But  we  find  highly  developed  administration  of  a  nongovernmental  char- 
acter in  other  institutional  realms  also.  Mooney  and  Reiley  have  under- 
scored the  importance,  especially  for  the  study  of  organization,  of  the  largely 
unexplored  riches  in  the  field  of  ecclesiastic  administration.1  The  Roman 
Catholic  Church  and  the  Greek  Orthodox  Church  come  to  mind  as  two 
conspicuous  examples.  These  and  other  religious  bodies  throughout  the 
world  have  maintained  themselves  continuously  through  many  centuries. 
Such  a  record  implies  remarkable  administrative  as  well  as  spiritual  achieve- 
ment. It  merits  more  attention  by  students  of  administration  than  it  has 
thus  far  received. 

Colleges  and  universities  comprise  another  institutional  sphere  which 
has  contributed  much  to  the  development  of  tested  administrative  knowl- 
edge. The  universities  of  Paris,  Oxford,  Palermo,  Cairo,  Salamanca,  Kiev, 
and  Harvard  are  but  a  few  of  many  outstanding  institutions  of  learning 
which  have  survived  through  hundreds  of  eventful  years  into  our  own 
time.  In  order  to  accomplish  their  intellectual  mission  they  had  to  give 
much  thought  to  the  administration  of  their  institutional  affairs.  Even 
today  few  problems  are  more  complex  than  those  of  giving  common  focus 
to  the  interests  of  professors,  students,  parents,  alumni,  trustees,  and  donors 
or  taxpayers — especially  when  we  consider  the  fact  that  most  of  these 
individuals  are  free  agents,  not  subject  to  compulsion. 

Scope  of  Public  Administration.  At  its  fullest  range,  public  adminis- 
tration embraces  every  area  and  activity  under  the  jurisdiction  of  public 
policy.  We  might  even  include  the  processes  and  operations  through  which 
the  legislative  branch  is  enabled  to  exercise  its  law-making  power;  there 
is  much  adroit  management  in  the  enactment  of  legislation.  In  the  literal 
sense  of  the  term,  public  administration  also  includes  the  functions  of  the 
courts — in  the  administration  of  justice — and  the  work  of  all  the  agencies, 
military  as  well  as  civilian,  in  the  executive  branch  of  government.  An 
exhaustive  treatise  on  public  administration  would,  therefore,  have  to  give 
consideration  to  judicial  structure  and  procedure  and  likewise  to  the  special 
machinery  and  methods  employed  by  the  armed  forces,  in  addition  to 

1  Mooney,  James  D.  and  Reiley,  Alan  C.,  The  Principles  of  Organization,  New  York: 
Harper,  1939,  especially  the  discussion  of  hierarchy  in  the  Roman  Catholic  Church  in  the  chapter 
on  "Theories  of  Organization." 


6  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

legislative  management.  By  established  usage,  however,  the  term  "public 
administration"  has  come  to  signify  primarily  the  organization,  personnel, 
practices,  and  procedures  essential  to  effective  performance  of  the  civilian 
functions  entrusted  to  the  executive  branch  of  government.  We  shall  use 
the  term  in  this  customary  sense,  (p 

While  not  disregarding  judicial  or  military  functions,  public  administra- 
tion in  our  meaning  denotes  mainly  the  work  of  civilian  agencies  charged 
by  statutory  mandate  with  carrying  on  the  public  business  assigned  to  them. 
Broadly  speaking,  it  covers  everything  they  do,  or  could  do,  to  help  the 
body  politic  attain  its  purposes|  More  specifically,  though  not  ignoring  con- 
siderations or  activities  peculiar  to  particular  governmental  levels,  types  of 
program,  or  geographic  areas, I  public  administration  centers  its  concern  in 
those  matters  of  organization,  procedure,  and  method  common  to  all  or 
most  administrative  agencies.  It  pertains  first  and  foremost  to  those  factors 
of  basic  importance  found  throughout  the  whole  range  of  executive  respon- 
sibility, j 

Application  of  the  body  of  knowledge  called  public  administration  to 
any  particular  function  like  welfare  may  carry  us  from  the  level  of  the 
town  hall  to  that  of  the  statehouse,  from  there  to  the  national  stage,  and 
on  beyond  to  international  affairs.  It  may  span,  on  a  single  plane,  from 
the  bogs  and  bayous  of  a  Louisiana  parish  to  the  desert  lands  of  a  county 
in  Nevada  or  the  wooded  hillsides  of  a  New  England  town.  It  may  impress 
identical  features  on  such  different  functions  as  health,  education,  conserva- 
tion, transportation,  telecommunication.  Or  it  may  weave  back  and  forth 
from  a  patently  "governmental"  function  like  the  arrest  and  detention  of  a 
thief,  to  a  quasi-governmental,  quasi-commercial  one  like  the  operation  of 
an  electrical  utility,  and  again  to  what  the  cynic  would  regard  as  a  public 
function  par  excellence,  the  collection  of  taxes.  Despite  the  shifting  scenes, 
certain  problems  will  recur  and  certain  precepts  will  be  uniformly  applicable 
in  every  field.  Generic  administrative  theory  is  everywhere  the  same;  its 
major  parts  comprise  the  "elements"  of  public  administration. 

Elements  of  Public  Administration.  The  fundamentals  of  organization, 
procedure,  and  method  essential  to  efficient  service  in  all  fields  alike,  irre- 
spective of  level,  area,  function,  or  purpose,  fall  into  three  principal  groups. 
Success  in  administration  is  a  composite  product  made  up  for  the  most 
part  of:  (a)  effective  relations  in  policy-making  between  the  chief  executive 
and  the  legislature  or,  in  the  case  of  a  private  enterprise,  the  board  of  direc- 
tors governing  the  organization;  (b)  ability  of  the  chief  executive  and  his 
principal  aides  and  key  subordinates  to  incorporate  the  policies  adopted 
by  the  legislature  or  board  of  directors  into  workable  plans  of  operation, 
sustained  by  appropriate  grouping  of  component  activities;  and  (c)  skill 
of  those  in  charge  of  operations  in  so  directing,  coordinating,  instructing, 
and  winning  the  collaboration  of  the  rank  and  file  of  employees  that  the 
objectives  embodied  in  policies  and  plans  will  be  efficiently  accomplished. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  7 

Thus  it  follows  that  the  elements  of  public  administration  consist  of  three 
sets  of  considerations  or  hypotheses:  the  first  pertaining  to  the  role  of  the 
executive  head  in  policy-making,  the  second  to  relations  between  that  official 
and  his  immediate  associates  in  the  top  structure  of  the  administrative 
hierarchy,  and  the  third  to  relations  between  the  higher  operating  chiefs 
and  all  employees  of  progressively  lower  rank.2 

Every  science  has  its  problems  of  nomenclature.  One  of  the  problems 
of  nomenclature  in  public  administration  has  been  to  develop  agreement 
on  terms  that  would  clearly  denote  the  three  major  aspects  or  phases  of 
this  science.  While  usage  has  not  become  firmly  settled,  the  highest  respon- 
sibilities— those  involving  relations  with  the  legislative  body — are  generally 
classified  as  being  executive  in  character.  Those  primarily  oriented  toward 
the  general  scheme  of  operations  are  usually  referred  to  as  administrative. 
Those  relating  to  the  actual  direction  and  supervision  of  the  whole  force  of 
employees  arc  in  the  main  labeled  managerial.  Managers  supervise  the  fulfill- 
ment of  work  programs  under  the  general  direction  of  administrators,  who 
in  turn  carry  responsibility  for  broad  assignments  given  them  by  the  chief 
executive,  whose  policies  are  formulated  in  collaboration  with  the  legislative 
body.  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  each  main  phase  of  responsibility 
carries  its  emphasis  into  the  body  of  aides  attached  to  it;  thus  the  chief  of  a 
departmental  planning  staff  is  an  administrative  aide. 

Administration  as  Servant  of  Policy.  Whether  the  sphere  of  interest  be 
public  or  private,  administration  is  always  the  servant  of  policy.  Manage- 
ment— the  largest  part  of  administration — denotes  means,  and  means  have 
no  significance  except  in  terms  of  ends.  The  dichotomy  of  ends  and  means 
forms  the  basis  of  and  supplies  the  justification  for  studying  public  adminis- 
tration as  an  identifiable  aspect  of  government.  We  usually  think  of  govern- 
ment as  being  divided  naturally  into  three  coordinate  parts — legislative, 
executive,  and  judicial.  It  is  desirable  to  recognize  the  utility  of  conceiving 
of  government  as  a  going  concern  having  but  two  main  phases — making 
public  policy  an^  administering  the  public  business  in  accordance  with 
that  policy. 

When  the  legislative  and  judicial  branches  of  our  national  and  state 
governments  confine  themselves  to  their  proper  functions,  the  former  con- 
cerns itself  mainly  with  problems  of  policy  and  the  latter  works  entirely 
in  the  field  of  administration — administering  justice.  In  contrast  with  these 
branches,  the  executive  department  is  obliged  to  a  certain  extent  to  carry  a 
double  load;  top  executives  have  to  labor  in  both  vineyards.  Presidents, 
governors,  and  mayors  (save  when  relieved  of  administrative  duties  by  a 
city  manager)  are  required  to  serve  both  as  political  leaders  and  adminis- 

3  See  Pearson,  Norman  M.,  "Fayolism  As  the  Necessary  Complement  of  Taylorism," 
American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  pp.  68-80.  For  further  elaboration,  see  Urwick, 
Lyndall,  The  Elements  of  Administration,  London:  Pitman,  1943. 


8  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

trative  chiefs.  Except  for  such  administrators-in-chief  and  their  principal 
subordinates,  however,  those  engaged  in  administration  do  not  make  or 
necessarily  participate  in  making  the  basic  policies  they  execute.  Their 
prime  job  is  to  give  effect  to  policy.  Their  main  function  is  the  execution 
of  programs.  The  sponsorship  or  authorization  of  programs  is  the  task  of 
policy-makers— the  elected  members  of  the  legislative  body  and  the  chief 
executive  with  his  associates. 

Translated  into  governmental  terms,  the  ends-means  scheme  becomes 
the  dichotomy  of  politics  and  administration.3  Admitting  its  relativities, 
this  is  a  useful  distinction.  It  is  of  practical  value  also  in  helping  free 
citizens  understand  what  they  can  most  wisely  do  in  making  democracy 
work.  The  political  tests  of  policy  are  mainly  two:  enlightenment  and 
representativeness.  The  citizen  can  force  his  government  to  meet  these 
tests  by  the  proper  use  of  his  vote.  In  contrast  there  is  only  one  main  test 
of  public  administration,  and  one  difficult  or  impossible  for  the  citizen  to 
apply:  Are  the  means  used  effective  in  terms  of  their  cost  in  achieving 
the  end  sought?  The  best  way  for  the  citizen  to  ensure  that  his  government 
meets  this  test  is  not  by  trying  to  measure  administrative  efficiency  himself 
but  by  making  his  elected  representatives  insist  on  the  use  of  objective 
measurement  of  performance  within  the  administrative  system. 

As  a  general  proposition,  policy  and  politics  in  the  sense  of  the  political 
process  of  policy  determination  are  primary  to  administration  both  logically 
and  chronologically.  Policy  defines  the  aims  and  ends  of  governmental 
action.  The  ideal  of  government  by  consent  of  the  governed  would  be 
empty  unless  the  common  man  had  his  say  in  the  matter.  In  a  democracy 
of  large-scale  governmental  operations  like  ours  the  citizen  plainly  cannot 
have  his  say  directly,  except  within  narrow  limits.  Through  voting,  how- 
ever, and  through  other  kinds  of  political  activity  he  can  indirectly  express 
his  preference  in  policy.  The  people  choose  their  representatives  in  the 
legislature  and  at  the  helm  of  the  executive  branch;  these  persons  proceed 
with  the  making  of  public  policy.  Though  they  may  receive  advice  and 
information  from  various  quarters — officials  as  well  as  interested  groups — 
they  alone  are  called  upon  to  determine  and  declare  policy. 

On  the  highest  level,  \therefore,  public  policy  is  what  politically  chosen 
representatives  make  it.  It  is  after  they  have  set  the  goals  and  laid  out  the 
main  lines  of  action  for  attaining  these  goals  that  the  basic  role  of  public 


8  For  two  classic  statements  of  this  distinction,  see  Wilson,  Woodrow,  "The  Study  of 
Administration,"  Political  Science  Quarterly,  1887,  Vol.  2,  pp.  197-222,  and  Goodnow,  Frank  J., 
Politics  and  Administration,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1900.  For  an  indication  of  current  views, 
see  Haines,  Charles  G.  and  Dimock,  Marshall  £.,  eds.,  Essays  on  the  Law  and  Practice  of 
Governmental  Administration,  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1935. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  9 

administration  begins.4  Administrators  have  the  task  of  enforcing  or  imple- 
menting policy  J  It  is  the  essence  of  their  craft  to  handle  the  public's  business 
with  the  greatest  efficiency  possible,  limited  only  by  the  resources  available 
to  them  and  the  conditions  under  whhh  they  are  required  to  work.  In 
their  capacity  as  citizens,  the  men  and  \\omen  who  serve  in  public  admin- 
istration may  not  always  share  the  views  of  those  who  make  official  policy 
or  agree  with  its  wisdom.  Unless  they  resign  their  posts,  however,  it  is 
their  solemn  duty  to  bend  every  effort  to  accomplish  the  purpose  or  the 
program  set.  It  is  not  their  business  to  try  to  substitute  any  greater  wisdom 
they  may  think  they  have  for  any  lesser  wisdom  of  the  people's  chosen 
representatives.  The  time  for  administrators  to  record  their  doubts  is  at 
the  stage  of  policy  consideration  or  reconsideration.  Here  they  will  usually 
be  heard  with  full  appreciation  of  their  judgment. 

The  public  service  has  much  to  gain  and  nothing  to  lose  from  observing 
the  implications  of  the  dichotomy  of  politics  and  administration.  To  the 
degree  that  administrative  officials  make  clear  by  word  and  deed  that  they 
regard  themselves  principally  as  agents  of  policy,  the  public  will  be  likelier 
to  confine  itself  to  the  control  of  policy  in  the  legislative  arena,  leaving 
administration  free  to  do  its  work  without  direct  political  interference. 

2.   THE  AMERICAN  BACKGROUND 

Heritage  from  Britain.  Five  European  nations  participated  in  the  ex- 
ploration and  early  settlement  of  what  is  now  the  continental  United  States. 
Only  one  of  them,  Britain,  left  a  deep  imprint  upon  our  administrative 
institutions.  British  antecedents  furnished  the  models  for  the  towns  which 
still  are  the  fundamental  political  units  in  New  England  and  for  the 
counties  which  form  the  basis  of  local  government  in  the  agrarian  South. 
The  mixed  pattern  of  towns,  townships,  cities,  and  counties  which  has 
developed  in  other  regions  of  the  country  also  arose  from  these  beginnings. 
The  combinations  and  modifications  which  took  place  have  been  due  mainly 
to  the  influence  of  geographic  and  economic  factors,  and  also  to  the  fact 
that  those  who  migrated  from  one  section  to  another  simply  carried  some 
of  their  customs  with  them. 

The  ad  hoc  or  special-purpose  governmental  districts — for  schools,  water, 
drainage,  health,  recreation — so  ubiquitous  in  American  local  administra- 
tion, are  likewise  to  a  degree  of  English  origin.  Gcnerically,  they  may  be 
traced  back  to  the  concept  of  the  limited  or  single-purpose  local  public  cor- 

4  The  sequence  of  politics  and  administration  is  perhaps  most  easily  visualized  with  refer- 
ence to  a  particular  statute  or  program.  There  are  at  least  five  stages  in  the  process,  the  first 
three  chiefly  political,  and  the  latter  two  mainly  administrative:  (a)  development  of  a  favorable 
public  opinion;  (b)  electioneering;  (c)  formal  legislative  adoption  or  enactment;  (d)  normal 
executive  administration,  continuing  as  long  as  the  policy  remains  unchanged;  and  (c)  judicial 
administration  for  interpretation  and  application  of  the  policy  whenever  the  citizen  claims 
thit  enforcement  would  invade  his  legal  rights.  Cf.  Anderson,  William,  American  City  Govern- 
mcnt,  pp.  188-1<>2.  New  York:  Henry  Holt,  1925. 


10  THE  GROWTH  OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

poration  as  developed  in  Anglo-Saxon  jurisprudence.  This  is  not  to  suggest, 
however,  that  the  explanation  for  our  extensive — not  to  say,  excessive — use 
of  these  units  is  bad  British  precedent.  The  historic  reason  for  our  having 
today  some  127,000  school  districts  is  not  that  our  ancestors  blindly  followed 
the  example  of  seventeenth-century  English  administrative  organization.  It 
was  partly  the  need  for  a  convenient  governmental  unit  through  which  early 
Americans,  especially  in  the  northern  colonies,  could  realize  their  ambition 
of  providing  free  common  schooling  for  all  children;  and  partly,  once  the 
pattern  of  reserving  sections  of  the  public  domain  for  the  support  of  educa- 
tion had  beeji  established,  the  necessity  for  a  device  whereby  the  people  of 
the  Northwest  Territory  (1787),  and  also  of  all  other  areas  subsequently 
opened  for  settlement,  could  organize  to  take  advantage  of  their  educational 
opportunities.  Whether  the  district  system  should  be  retained  unchanged 
or  whether  it  should  be  modified  and  simplified  are  questions  to  which 
students  of  public  administration  in  the  twentieth  century  must  find  answers. 

Until  the  first  gains,  during  World  War  I,  of  the  movement  for 
state  administrative  reorganization,  perhaps  the  best  way  to  describe  the 
impact  of  the  British  example  on  state  government  would  have  been  in 
terms  of  "reverse  English."  American  experience  with  royal  colonial  admin- 
istration had  been  such  that,  when  the  people  themselves  came  into  control 
after  1776,  they  reversed  the  model  of  the  powerful  chief  executive.  In 
organizing  their  new  state  governments  they  vested  preponderant  power  in 
the  legislative  assembly.  Aside  from  the  presidency,  it  took  the  nation 
approximately  a  century  to  overcome  its  fears  and  suspicions  of  centralized 
authority,  even  under  popular  and  legislative  control.  The  movement  for 
administrative  integration  under  a  strengthened  executive  which  has  been 
the  key  to  much  of  the  progress  made  in  state  government  during  the  past 
generation  is  a  relatively  recent  development. 

Insofar  as  the  form  and  character  of  American  national  government  is 
concerned,  the  Constitution  on  which  it  is  based  comprises  a  bundle  of  com- 
promises. One  of  the  reasons  why  compromise  was  so  essential  in  the  his- 
toric summer  of  1787  was  the  insistence  of  many  of  the  Founding  Fathers 
that  the  document  incorporate  numerous  features  of  the  British  system  of 
government.  They  aimed  at  framing  a  polity  combining  both  aristocratic 
and  democratic  characteristics,  but  in  such  a  way  that  over  the  years  the 
popular  features  could  gradually  be  expanded.  Every  mature  citizen  may 
judge  for  himself  how  well  they  succeeded. 

Finally,  there  is  the  matter  of  English  ideals  of  liberty,  equality,  and 
justice.  Our  British  heritage  has  not  consisted  merely  of  mechanics  related 
to  administrative  areas  and  structures.  In  some  ways  the  most  significant 
elements  have  been  those  conceptions  of  individual  freedom,  due  process, 
and  equal  justice  which,  adding  up  to  the  "rule  of  law,"  are  perhaps  the 
richest  political  treasure  of  American  as  well  as  of  Anglo-Saxon  civilization. 
Americans  have  introduced  many  modifications  in  their  administrative  as  in 


GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  11 

their  linguistic  heritage.  Yet  these  have  not  replaced  the  foundations. 
British  influence  lives  in  American  administration  today  not  only  in  its  struc- 
tural forms  and  operating  procedures  but  still  more  in  the  spirit  by  which 
the  whole  system  is  animated. 

Influence  of  the  Frontier.  As  part  of  the  "cutting  edge  of  civilization," 
public  administration  is  always  affected  at  any  given  time  by  what  civiliza- 
tion is  trying  to  cut.  When  it  is  the  wilderness  of  untamed  forests,  prairies, 
swamps,  and  deserts  with  which  American  government  had  to  contend  for 
three  hundred  years  as  the  pioneers  made  their  way  westward  across  the 
continent,  the  effects  are  of  one  kind.  When  civilization  is  cutting  economic 
or  social  barriers  in  a  highly  industrialized  and  urbanized  society,  the  effects 
are  of  a  different  nature. 

The  physical  frontiers  against  which  American  civilization  was  pushing 
from  the  days  of  the  landings  at  St.  Augustine,  Jamestown,  and  Plymouth 
until  the  last  of  the  good  "free  land"  was  staked  and  claimed  around  1890 
had  several  major  influences  upon  the  emerging  administrative  system. 
Sparsity  of  population  and  the  simple  life  which  the  pioneers  and  first  set- 
tlers led,  together  witl\  their  fierce  spirit  of  self-reliance,  caused  the  activity 
of  government  to  be  restricted  at  the  outset  to  little  more  than  the  main- 
tenance of  the  peace,  the  recording  of  land  titles  and  the  administration  of 
justice.  As  a  result,  the  ideal  of  limited  government  became  deeply  ingrained 
in  American  political  thought.  This  in  turn  encouraged  the  view,  asserted 
on  a  national  scale  by  Andrew  Jackson,  that  the  duties  of  public  employees 
were,  or  admitted  of  being  made,  so  simple  that  as  a  general  rule  they  could 
be  performed  in  a  reasonably  satisfactory  manner  by  the  ordinary  citizen, 
irrespective  of  the  character  of  his  previous  private  pursuits.  Honesty  and 
normal  intelligence  were  thought  to  be  the  only  essential  qualifications. 

These  influences  have  expressed  themselves  chiefly  in  two  ways.  One 
has  been  the  constant  disposition  of  the  public  to  be  suspicious  of  all  pro- 
posals to  extend  the  range  of  administrative  activity.  Millions  of  Americans 
still  hold  the  conviction  that  government  should  both  stay  out  of  business 
and  keep  away  from  it — the  late  nineteenth-century  version  of  Jefferson's 
preference  for  that  government  which  governed  least.  The  other  influence 
has  been  a  somewhat  naive  faith  in  mechanically  simple  and  direct  relation- 
ships between  the  citizen  and  his  public  servants,  coupled  with  a  stubborn 
refusal  to  combine  defectively  small  governmental  units  into  larger  and 
more  resourceful  entities.  Until  near  the  _  close  of  the  nineteenth  century, 
virtually  every  important  administrative  office— wHetrier  IrTtown,  city,  school 
district,  county,  or  state — was  on  an  elective  basis.  Many  still  are,  particu- 
larly in  the  counties.  Moreover,  terms  of  elective  office  are  invariably  short3 
seldom  running  over  two  years. 

As  for  appointive  positions,  the  presumption  prevailed  from  the  early 
days  that  there  should  be  frequent  rotation  in  office  and  that  every  newly 
elected  official  had  the  right  to  dismiss  incumbents  inherited  from  his  pre- 


12  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

decessor  and  fill  their  posts  with  appointees  of  his  own  choosing.  Con- 
siderable success  has  been  achieved  on  the  national  level  and  in  the  more 
progressive  states  and  cities  in  replacing  this  tradition  by  the  sounder  one 
of  career  service  based  on  merit.  However,  the  old  way  remains  dominant 
over  a  considerable  area  of  public  administration  even  to  this  day. 

Hamiltonian  and  feffersonian  Traditions.  Another  historic  influence  upon 
modern  American  administration  has  been  the  unceasing  contest  between 
two  different  governmental  theories  espoused  by  the  two  opposing  titans 
of  Washington's  original  cabinet.5 

Hamilton,  brilliant,  logical,  and  conservative,  believed  that  commercial 
strength  constituted  the  only  sure  foundation  for  national  welfare  and 
favored  bold  use  of  federal  authority  to  advance  that  end.  His  program 
for  building  up  a  business  class  through  tariff  protection  and  other  aids  to 
industry  inevitably  entailed  a  considerable  exercise  of  centralized  power. 
This  caused  opposition  at  a  time  when  previous  experience  led  most  people 
to  cavil  at  every  debatable  employment  of  public  authority  as  a  danger  to 
individual  liberty.  Hamilton,  however,  had  no  fear  of  power  in  government 
provided  that  those  who  wielded  it  could  be  held  responsible  for  their  acts. 
This  philosophy  has  been  a  significant  factor  in  American  government. 
Disillusionment  with  the  consequences  of  his  economic  approach  has  weak- 
ened the  appeal  of  Hamilton's  program  at  various  times.  It  is  hardly  too 
much  to  say,  however,  that  his  philosophy  of  administration — readiness  to 
use  governmental  power  wherever  there  is  assurance  of  public  control  over 
its  use — is  stronger  today  than  ever  before. 

Jefferson,  his  great  antagonist,  disagreed  with  these  ideas — though  not 
with  a  policy  of  fostering  the  development  of  commerce  or  of  using  such 
power  as  was  indispensable  to  the  attainment  of  some  end  that  would  greatly 
enhance  the  public  welfare.  Visualizing  the  country  as  destined  under  the 
right  leadership  to  develop  into  a  glorious  agrarian  democracy  in  which 
every  man  could  find  security  for  his  family  in  the  cultivation  of  his  own 
acreage  or  in  independent  work  as  artisan,  Jefferson  saw  little  need  for 
national  administration  other  than  that  required  for  the  conduct  of  foreign 
relations. 

Beneath  this  belief,  however,  lay  a  more  fundamental  conviction.  Jef- 
ferson was  of  the  opinion  that  power  always  tends  to  corrupt  the  man  in 
whom  it  is  vested.  He  considered  the  difficulties  of  preventing  its  abuse  so 
formidable  as  to  make  imperative  its  limitation  to  the  barest  minimum. 
Jefferson's  agrarian  ideal  has  long  since  lost  all  chance  of  translation  into 
actuality.  However,  no  one  needs  to  be  told  that  because  of  the  continued 
and  gradually  increasing  expansion  of  central  government,  this  philosophy 
of  limited  and  decentralized  administration  is  one  of  the  most  effective  rally- 
ing cries  for  many  who  are  earnestly  concerned  over  the  future  of  American 

5  Cf.     Caldwell,    Lynton    K.,    The   Administrative    Theories   of  Hamilton   and  Jefferson, 
Chicago:   University  of  Chicago  Press,  1944. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  13 

federalism.    There  are  simultaneously  groups  within  the  body  politic  who 
are  exploiting  the  fear  of  power  for  selfish  purposes. 

Clearly,  neither  the  Hamiltonian  nor  the  Jeffersonian  tradition  embraces 
the  whole  truth.  Public  administration  has  profited  by  accepting  parts  of 
both.  The  problem  has  been — and  will  continue  to  be — how  much  em- 
phasis at  a  given  time  to  accord  to  each. 

Public  Administration  and  the  National  Economy.  Adam  Smith's  The 
Wealth  of  Nations,  published  in  the  year  of  the  American  declaration  of 
political  independence,  served  in  a  sense  as  a  declaration  of  economic  inde- 
pendence on  behalf  of  the  rising  business  or  middle  class.  As  such  its  basic 
ideas  came  to  have  an  enormous  vogue  throughout  the  whole  Western  world. 
It  is  no  exaggeration  to  say  that  during  the  nineteenth  century  they  sup- 
plied the  dominant  coloration  in  popular  thought  on  the  relations  between 
government  and  business.  Nor  have  they  ceased  to  exert  their  influence. 
The  philosophy  of  classical  economics  which  took  its  rise  from  this  epic 
volume  was  far  more  than  a  reasoned  protest  against  the  theory  and  practice 
of  mercantilism.  It  had  a  positive  character  of  its  own,  the  implications  of 
which  were  of  cardinal  importance  for  public  administration. 

Politics  and  economics,  according  to  Adam  Smith,  were  largely  separate 
spheres.  The  less  they  had  to  do  with  each  other,  the  better.  Every  man 
had  his  own  property  or  skill  and  the  impulse  of  self-interest  to  lead  him 
to  put  them  to  the  best  employment.  The  wisest  thing  government  could 
do,  therefore,  to  help  men  solve  their  economic  problems  was  to  leave  the 
business  world  strictly  alone.  Admittedly  it  was  necessary  for  government 
to  prevent  or  suppress  civil  disturbances,  punish  crime,  and  build  and  main- 
tain basic  public  works.  In  the  domestic  realm  at  least,  however,  this  was 
as  far  as  it  should  go. 

With  a  virgin  continent  opening  up  in  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth 
centuries,  great  numbers  of  the  people  of  the  United  States  had  property  of 
their  own — land  being  naturally  the  main  type;  or,  lacking  property,  they 
could  acquire  some.  Land  enabled  a  family  to  be  relatively  self-sufficient. 
Consequently,  the  philosophy  of  governmental  nonintervention  did  no  such 
violence  to  the  economic  facts  of  life  as  it  would  in  our  day.  Widespread 
ownership  of  land,  actual  and  potential,  provided  at  least  some  justification 
for  laissez  jaire  government.  Another  factor  was  the  neat  complementation 
of  legal  theory:  it  was,  and  is,  one  of  the  basic  tenets  of  the  "rule  of  law" 
here  as  in  England  that  the  citizen  is  at  liberty  to  do  whatever  has  not  been 
prohibited,  provided  only  that  he  recognize  the  equal  right  of  everyone  else 
to  act  in  the  same  way. 

It  required,  therefore,  a  long  and  slow  development,  through  decades 
blotted  with  innumerable  instances  of  helpless  poverty  and  social  injustice, 
to  raise  political  thinking  above  the  standard  of  freedom  from  regulation  of 
any  kind  to  a  higher  standard.  This  higher  standard  of  the  present  age  is 
freedom  under  regulation  designed  to  safeguard  the  general  welfare.  Until 


14  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

the  new  development  was  well  under  way,  public  administration  had  only 
halting  and  tentative  relationships  with  the  national  economy.  Today  gov- 
ernmental activities  in  countless  ways  sustain  our  economic  life. 

Assertion  of  the  Public  Interest.  Charles  E.  Merriam  has  pointed  out 
in  a  recent  study  of  public  planning  that  in  the  early  decades  of  the  last 
century  the  federal  government  showed  some  concern  over  abuses  inherent 
in  uncontrolled  private  exploitation  of  the  nation's  natural  resources.  Yet 
it  was  not  until  the  eighties  that  practical  action  was  initiated  to  safeguard 
the  public  interest.6  Following  the  panic  of  1837,  Massachusetts  established 
a  state  bank  commission  to  make  sure  thereafter  of  the  observance  of  it? 
banking  regulations.  Still,  even  though  there  was  similar  provocation  ir 
other  states,  few  followed  suit.7  Jurisdiction  over  such  matters  lay  generall) 
with  the  states;  their  inaction  often  resulted  in  hardship  and  injustice  foi 
numerous  individuals.  Nevertheless,  it  was  only  after  the  Middle  Westerr 
states  had  enacted  the  Granger  laws  in  the  seventies  that  government  begar 
to  intervene  more  extensively  in  the  economic  sphere. 

Conceivably,  the  executive  arm  of  the  national  government  might  hav< 
been  employed  to  prevent  the  occurrence  of  abuses  as  the  economy  of  th< 
country  expanded.  However,  any  effort  toward  effective  use  of  publi< 
authority  for  such  purposes  would  have  met  the  strongest  kind  of  opposition 
From  the  history  of  governmental  regulation  during  the  late  nineteend 
century  it  is  evident  that  the  new  public  administration  was  in  a  sense  th< 
unwanted  child  of  a  nation  bent  on  the  wild  pursuit  of  material  gain.  Gros 
rapacity  and  prodigal  wastage  had  to  demonstrate  the  error  in  the  belie 
that  competition  invariably  worked  like  an  invisible  hand  to  ensure  the  prc 
tection  and  promotion  of  the  common  welfare.  Only  then  did  the  represen 
tative  bodies  begin  to  emphasize  the  positive  note  in  the  American  phi! 
osophy  of  government — the  idea  that  government  exists  to  safeguard  th 
general  welfare.  Only  then  did  they  enact  the  statutes  and  create  the  agencie 
which  account  for  the  contemporary  range  of  public  administration. 

3.    THE  EXPANSION  OF  GOVERNMENTAL  FUNCTIONS 

American  Pragmatism.  With  some  measure  of  justification,  it  has  bee 
said  of  the  people  of  the  United  States  that  as  a  nation  they  are  not  muc 
given  to  systematic  political  speculation.  Throughout  our  history  it  has  ger 
erally  been  assumed  without  benefit  of  particulars  that  the  sphere  of  goverr 
mental  activity  should  be  sharply  limited  and  that  government  should  "sta 
out  of  business."  No  one,  however,  has  succeeded  in  making  a  list  of  propc 
and  improper  functions  of  government  that  has  won  public  approval  an 
held  it  over  an  extended  period.  William  Graham  Sumner's  What  Do  Socit 

6  Merriam,  Charles  E.,  "The  National  Resources  Planning  Board:    A  Chapter  in  America 
Planning  Experience,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1075  ff. 

7  Cf.   White,  Leonard  D.,  Introduction  to  the  Study  of  Public  Administration,  pp.  26-2 
New  York:  Macmillan,  rev  ed.,  1939. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  15 

Classes  Owe  Each  Other?  (1883)  and  Herbert  Spencer's  Man  Versus  the 
State  (1884)  both  endeavored  to  demonstrate  analytically  why  it  was  unwise 
to  enlarge  the  range  of  governmental  action.  Yet  the  functions  of  govfern- 
ment  were  increased  even  during  the  decades  in  which  these  books  were 
enjoying  their  greatest  popularity.  Though  their  theoretical  inclination  has 
consistently  been  to  keep  the  scope  of  government  restricted,  the  American 
people  have  shown  equal  consistency  in  basing  their  action  on  "practical 
considerations"  whenever  these  have  pointed  strongly  in  the  opposite  direc- 
tion. 

The  line  of  argument  implied  in  Cleveland's  famous  sentence,  "It  is  a 
condition  and  not  a  theory  which  confronts  us,"  is  one  that  has  always  made 
sense  to  most  Americans.  They  tend  to  believe  that  the  presumption  should 
never  be  in  favor  of  adding  to  the  powers  or  responsibilities  of  government; 
but  they  also  insist  that  in  the  last  analysis  "government  has  to  do  what  it 
has  to  do."8  They  have  never  been  prepared  to  adhere  blindly  to  mere  theory 
when  the  price  of  such  adherence  would  have  been  acute  social  injustice  or 
failure  to  reach  some  objective  to  which  they  were  strongly  attached.  It 
remains  to  be  seen  how  far  attitudes  will  change  in  the  face  of  the  new  con- 
cern for  high-level  employment.  Up  to  now,  however,  Americans  have 
tended  to  support  the  broad  principle  that  government  should  not  meddle 
in  the  domain  of  economic  affairs  and  at  the  same  time  they  have  wanted  it 
to  be  prepared  to  help  them  meet  whatever  economic  difficulties  might  prove 
to  be  beyond  the  capacity  of  business. 

Limits  to  Governmental  Nonintervention.  American  administrative  his- 
tory abounds  in  illustrations  of  governmental  extensions  to  meet  current 
needs.  Consider,  for  instance,  the  compromise  of  laissez  faire  involved  in 
the  erection  of  national  tariff  walls,  in  the  establishment  of  the  three  "clien- 
tele" departments  in  Washington — Agriculture,  Commerce,  and  Labor — and 
in  the  creation  of  certain  of  our  governmental  corporations.  Each  of  these 
developments  represents  something  of  a  variation  on  the  theme  of  the  pure 
theory  of  the  American  politico-economic  system,  yet  each  is  accepted  as  a 
part  of  the  system  in  operation.  Curiously  enough,  those  who  show  the 
greatest  interest  in  urging  government  to  pursue  or  persist  in  a  positive  course 
of  action  are  often  quite  unconscious  of  what  they  do  in  terms  of  this  theory. 
The  reason  is  simple.  If  a  particular  group  can  manage  to  persuade  govern- 
ment to  intervene  in  the  economic  sphere  on  behalf  of  its  own  special 
interest,  that  naturally  seems  to  it  all  to  the  good;  it  is  "interference"  only 
in  the  eyes  of  those  who  are  interfered  with — to  them  it  is  all  wrong. 

Few  groups  in  the  body  politic  have  given  more  lip  service  to  the  prin- 
ciple of  the  separation  of  government  and  business  than  the  leaders  of 
industry.  They  have  always  held  it  high  as  a  general  idea.  Yet  from  the 
time  of  Alexander  Hamilton  to  the  present  they  have  generally  favored 

8  For  the  nature  of  the  people's  power  over  public  administration,  see  Appleby,  Paul  H., 
Big  Democracy,  p.  135  ff.,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


16  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

tariff  protection — a  clear  illustration  of>  artificial  interference  with  the  dis- 
pensations of  the  "invisible  hand"  of  foft  and  "natural"  competition.  Nor  is 
it  relevant  that  many  believers  in  laissez  jaire  have  fought  for  tariffs  with- 
out being  aware  of  their  inconsistency.  Their  leaders  have  usually  known 
what  they  were  doing.  As  practical  men  they  have  merely  refused  to  allow 
intangible  principles  to  stand  in  the  way  of  tangible  results. 

Establishment  of  Clientele  Departments.  Governmental  intervention  in 
the  field  of  agriculture  began  nationally  in  an  almost  unnoticed  activity  of 
the  Patent  Office — the  distribution  of  seeds  and  cuttings  received  from 
American  consuls  abroad.  After  performing  this  humble  service  for  a 
number  of  years,  the  Patent  Office  in  1839  was  given  its  first  agricultural 
appropriation  of  $1,000.  This  was  to  be  used  for  continued  collection  and 
distribution  of  seeds,  for  making  several  investigations  of  interest  to  farmers, 
and  for  the  collection  of  agricultural  statistics.  Succeeding  years  brought 
increased  appropriations  without  additional  functions.  Then,  in  1862,  under 
the  urging  of  the  United  States  Agricultural  Society  whose  members  wanted 
additional  "service"  from  the  government,  Congress  took  the  decisive  step 
of  passing  the  "organic  act"  which  created  "at  the  seat  of  government  of  the 
United  States  a  Department  of  Agriculture/*9 

It  is  a  far  cry  from  these  modest  beginnings  to  the  gigantic  operations  of 
the  department  today.  But  two  strong  threads  have  provided  connecting 
ties  throughout  every  stage  of  the  development.  One  is  the  continuous  desire 
of  organized  farmers  for  governmental  aid  to  agriculture.  What  the  United 
States  Agricultural  Society  did  in  persuading  Congress  to  establish  a  new 
department  in  the  midst  of  the  Civil  War  typifies  what  organized  agriculture 
has  tried  to  do  ever  since — gain  for  itself  in  the  solution  of  its  problems  the 
friendly  assistance  of  government.  The  other  thread  is  the  willingness  of 
the  public  to  "go  along."  Occasionally  it  does  so  for  the  positive  reason  that 
it  thinks  the  general  welfare  would  be  served  by  providing  the  help  sought. 
The  usual  explanation  is  much  simpler,  however.  Unless  the  opponents  of 
a  proposal  can  convince  the  public  that  its  passage  would  open  the  door  to 
a  raid  on  the  treasury,  it  is  almost  impossible  to  rally  a  majority  to  block  its 
enactment. 

The  Department  of  Commerce  and  Labor,  created  in  1903,  was  the  sec- 
ond major  clientele  agency  established  within  the  structure  of  national 
administration.  In  terms  of  its  germinal  bureaus,  it  rose  from  such  practical 
considerations  as  the  necessity  for  proper  patent  registration  (Superintendent 
of  Patents,  1802),  the  need  for  inspection  of  steamboats  to  ensure  their  sea- 
worthy condition  (Steamboat  Inspection  Service,  1838),  and  the  demand  on 
government  for  maintaining  a  testing  laboratory  of  its  own  in  order  to  assure 
itself  of  getting  full  and  precise  value  in  the  purchase  of  supplies  (National 
Bureau  of  Standards,  1901).  In  terms  of  its  creation  as  a  combined  entity, 

®Gaus,  John  M.  and  Wolcott,  Leon  O.,  Public  Administration  and  the  United  States 
Department  of  Agriculture,  pp.  3-5,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1940. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  17 

the  Department  of  Commerce  and  Labor  owed  its  origin  to  the  fact  that 
around  the  turn  of  the  century  the  President  and  Congress  alike  were  con- 
vinced that  administrative  needs  would  better  be  served  by  bringing  togethei 
twelve  existing  bureaus  doing  broadly  related  work  in  a  single,  fairly  unified 
agency. 

The  unit  within  the  Department  of  Commerce  and  Labor  which  has 
aided  the  American  business  community  most  directly  came  into  being  as 
the  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce.  Established  in  1912  by  an 
act  of  Congress,  it  was  charged  specifically  with  the  "the  promotion  and 
development  of  the  foreign  and  domestic  commerce  of  the  United  States." 
Organized  business  worked  actively  for  the  passage  of  the  measure  setting 
up  the  new  bureau  and  has  since  then  looked  upon  the  department,  not 
unreasonably,  as  its  special  source  of  sympathetic  governmental  assistance. 

Like  the  Department  of  Commerce  (from  which  in  1913  it  was  formed 
by  separation),  the  Department  of  Labor  was  composed  initially  of  two 
bureaus  which  had  been  created  in  preceding  years.  The  older  of  these  was 
the  Bureau  of  Labor,  established  by  Congress  in  1884  for  the  purpose  of 
collecting  and  analyzing  information  on  labor  conditions  and  located  in  the 
Department  of  the  Interior.  Named  the  Department  of  Labor  a  few  years 
later  and  given  independent  status  though  not  cabinet  rank,  it  was  in  1903 
again  designated  as  a  bureau  and  grouped  with  a  number  of  other  agencies 
to  form  the  Department  of  Commerce  and  Labor.  The  other  original  ele- 
ment of  the  newly  formed  Department  of  Labor  was  the  Children's  Bureau, 
which  had  been  in  existence  for  less  than  a  year.  As  its  name  implies,  the 
Children's  Bureau  was  created  for  the  purpose  of  gathering  information 
and  preparing  reports,  nationwide  in  scope,  on  problems  of  child  care  and 
child  welfare.  The  considerations  leading  the  President  and  Congress  to 
combine  the  two  bureaus  into  a  department  of  cabinet  rank  were  political 
and  administrative.  With  organized  labor's  increasing  success  in  making 
the  public  aware  of  the  problems  of  the  working  class,  it  appeared  to  be 
both  "good  politics"  and  sound  administrative  grouping  to  accord  labor  the 
same  kind  of  recognition  which  had  already  been  given  to  agriculture  and 
business. 

Rise  of  Governmental  Corporations.  As  American  pragmatism  is  evi- 
dent in  the  creation  of  these  three  great  clientele  departments,  so  it  can  be 
seen  just  as  plainly  in  the  circumstances  under  which  some  of  our  govern- 
mental proprietary  undertakings  were  launched.  With  popular  opinion 
generally  adverse  to  government's  "going  into  business,"  most  proposals  to 
set  up  a  publicly  owned  or  publicly  operated  business  enterprise  have  a  strike 
or  two  against  them  before  they  get  under  way.  Yet  government  corpora- 
tions are  by  no  means  uncommon  on  the  American  administrative  scene. 
Many  urban  communities  throughout  the  country  have  established  their 
own  corporate  enterprises  in  the  field  of  municipal  utilities.  When  the  citi- 
zens found  themselves  unable  to  obtain  satisfactory  water,  electric,  gas,  or 


18  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

transit  service  at  reasonable  rates  through  private  firms,  they  took  what 
seemed  to  them  the  logical  second  course  of  using  their  local  government  to 
set  up  and  operate  its  own  facilities. 

As  a  rule  the  states  have  had  little  need  for  such  corporate  enterprises 
of  their  own.  For  a  variety  of  reasons,  however,  the  national  government  has 
made  increasing  use  of  corporate  organization  during  the  past  thirty  years. 
During  World  War  I,  for  instance,  a  governmental  corporation  was  formed 
for  so  vital  a  purpose  as  the  expediting  of  an  emergency  shipbuilding  pro- 
gram. Several  such  corporations  were  formed  during  the  years  of  the  Great 
Depression  to  aid  economic  interests,  and  especially  to  make  and  administer 
loans  to  business  firms  in  need  of  credit  and  unable  to  obtain  it  from  private 
sources.  The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  created  in  1933,  was  given  cor- 
porate status  so  that  it  might  enjoy  the  greatest  possible  measure  of  adminis- 
trative freedom  and  flexibility  in  developing  its  unique  program  of  regional 
rehabilitation,  including  cooperation  toward  that  goal  with  the  people  of 
the  region  through  their  local  organizations,  both  governmental  and  private. 
In  World  War  II,  to  take  but  one  of  many  examples,  the  national  govern- 
ment organized  the  United  States  Commercial  Corporation  because  of  the 
need  for  an  agency  through  which  it  could  act  with  convenience  and  dis- 
patch and  with  a  minimum  of  publicity  in  waging  certain  forms  of  economic 
warfare.  It  is  clear,  therefore,  that  the  serious  public  reservations  against 
proliferation  of  governmental  activities  have  not  barred  the  use  of  govern- 
ment corporations  when  the  people  have  been  unable  to  satisfy  their  needs 
through  the  services  of  private  enterprise. 

Growth  of  Administrative  Activities.  The  response  of  government  in 
this  country  to  what  the  late  Justice  Holmes  called  "the  felt  necessities  of  the 
time,"  has  meant  that  the  United  States,  like  other  modern  nations,  has 
experienced  during  the  last  century  a  great  transition.  Before  the  steam 
engine,  the  locomotive,  the  automobile,  the  telephone,  the  radio,  the  airplane, 
and  other  marvels  of  science  and  technology  made  our  civilization  what  it  is, 
the  responsibilities  of  government  were  not  only  quite  limited  but  on  the 
whole  largely  negative  in  character.  So  great,  however,  and  so  unsettling 
has  been  the  impact  of  scientific  inventions  upon  the  conditions  under  which 
the  vast  majority  of  people  live  and  work  that  the  police  activities  of  govern- 
ment have  long  come  to  be  overshadowed  by  others  of  a  more  positive 
character.  The  police  state  of  former  times  has  retreated  to  make  room  for 
the  service  or  welfare  state;  yet  in  a  sense  the  two  still  exist  side  by  side. 

The  nature  of  this  transformation  may  be  seen  very  plainly  in  the  tre- 
mendous expansion  of  municipal  administration.  Cincinnati  and  Detroit, 
during  the  period  from  the  early  1800's  down  to  the  1930's  grew  from  com- 
munities whose  municipal  services  could  be  numbered  on  the  fingers  of  one's 
hands  to  metropolitan  regions  whose  services  totaled  between  three  and 
four  hundred.  And  the  end  is  not  yet.  The  log  of  administrative  develop- 
ment of  both  these  cities  makes  it  clear  that  protection  of  life  and  property 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  19 

continues  to  be  an  important  municipal  responsibility.  It  demonstrates  even 
more  conspicuously,  however,  that  it  is  activities  in  the  fields  of  health,  utili- 
ties, education,  recreation,  and  social  welfare  which  mainly  absorb  the 
energies  of  urban  government  in  the  present  age.10 

Comparative  studies  of  state  and  county  governments  likewise  show  up- 
ward trends  in  the  number  and  variety  of  their  administrative  activities.11 
The  rate  of  increase,  however,  is  here  markedly  lower  than  in  the  case  of 
municipalities,  owing  to  the  fact  that  the  main  currents  of  modern  life — 
the  trends  toward  national  economic  organization  and  urban  residence — 
have  affected  states  and  counties  to  a  lesser  degree.  In  the  case  of  the  national 
government  the  trend  line  rises  steeply.  Comprehensive  statistical  indices 
are  available  only  for  selected  periods;  but  the  crude  data  themselves  give 
eloquent  testimony  of  the  steadily  increasing  use  the  American  people  have 
made  of  their  central  government.12  Annual  budget  expenditures  and 
civilian  personnel  figures  have  both  risen  at  rates  far  in  advance  of  the  rate 
of  population  growth.  While  the  following  table  does  not  suggest  the  nature 
of  the  new  responsibilities  the  national  government  has  acquired  in  recent 
decades,  it  does  afford  some  indication  of  the  extent  to  which  the  volume  of 
governmental  activities  has  grown. 

INCREASE  IN  NATIONAL  POPUIAIION,  ANNUAL  EXPENDITURES  AND  ADMINISTRATIVE 
PERSONNEL  BY  Di CADES  DURING  THE  CENTURY  1840-1940 

Annual  Expenditures 


Vear 

1840  

1850 

1860        ...  ... 

1870 
1880       . 
1890 

1900          .  

1910      ... 

1920  

1930 
1940 

*  U.  S.  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Sixteenth  Census  of  the  United  States,  1940:    Population, 
Vol.  1,  p.  6,  Washington,  1942. 

**U.  S.  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  Annual  Report,  1943,  pp.  466-471,  Washington,  1944. 

***U.  S.   Bureau  of  the  Census,  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  States,  1943,  p.  165, 
Washington,  1944.   The  figures  given  are  for  the  years  1841,  1851,  1861,  etc. 


ipulation  of 

of  the  National 

Civilian  Employees 

'ontinental 

Government,  excluding 

in  the  Federal 

Mted  States* 

debt  retirement** 

Executive 

n  millions) 

(in  dollars) 

Service*** 

17.0 

24,317,579 

23,700 

23.2 

39,543,492 

33,300 

31.4 

63,130,598 

49,200 

38.6 

309,653,561 

53,900 

50.2 

267,642,958 

107,000 

63.0 

318,040,711 

166,000 

76.0 

520,860,847 

256,000 

92.0 

693,617,065 

391,350 

105.7 

6,403,343,841 

562,252 

122.8 

3,440,268,884 

588,206 

131.7 

8,998,189,706 

1,370,110 

10  Cf.    Upson,  Lent  D.,  The  Growth  of  a  City  Government,  Detroit:  Bureau  of  Municipal 
Research,   1931;  Cincinnati  Municipal  Reference  Bureau,  Cincinnati  (1802-1936):    The  March 
of  City  Government,  Cincinnati,  1937. 

11  For   a   charting  of   the   administrative  growth   of  state  government,  see  Hurt,   Elsey, 
California  State  Government:    An   Outline  of  its  Administrative  Organization  from   1850  to 
1936.  2  vols.,  Sacramento:    California  State  Printing  Office,  1937-1939. 

12  See  Wooddy,  Carroll   H.,  The  Growth  of  the  Federal  Government,  1915-1932,  New 
York:    McGraw-Hill,   1934.    This  study  was  published  as  one  of  the  monographs  supporting 
the  report  of  President  Hoover's  Commission  on  Recent  Social  Trends. 


20  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

The  salient  fact  about  the  character  of  the  newer  activities  of  the  federal 
government — namely,  that  they  are  designed  to  cope  with  the  impact  of 
technology  on  American  society — is  patent  from  the  names  of  some  of  the 
principal  agencies  which  have  been  created  since  the  turn  of  the  century.  A 
partial  list  would  include:  Department  of  Commerce  (and  Labor),  1903; 
Department  of  Labor,  1913;  Federal  Reserve  System,  1913;  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  1914;  United  States  Tariff  Commission,  1916;  Federal  Power 
Commission,  1920;  Federal  Communications  Commission,  1934;  Securities 
and  Exchange  Commission,  1934;  National  Labor  Relations  Board,  1935. 
Each  of  these  agencies  was  established  to  deal  with  specific  problems,  and 
each  has  in  some  measure  accomplished  the  purpose  for  which  it  was  created. 
Obviously,  however,  we  have  not  reached  the  end  of  the  road.  New  prob- 
lems have  arisen  since  the  youngest  of  these  agencies  was  brought  into  being. 
Others  will  arise  in  the  future. 

In  organizing  an  agency  to  deal  with  a  particular  issue,  the  President  and 
Congress — or  a  governor  and  a  state  legislature,  a  mayor  and  a  city  council 
— may  dispose  of  that  immediate  issue,  but  often  at  the  price  of  various 
procedural  irritations  within  the  administrative  system  as  a  whole.  It  is 
invariably  something  of  a  problem  to  coordinate  the  work  of  a  new  agency 
with  that  of  older  units  doing  related  work.  Especially  where  there  is  no 
attempt  to  weigh  the  advantages  of  alternative  methods  of  organization  and 
operation,  the  problem  of  coordination  can  become  quite  troublesome. 

4.    INCREASING  COMPETENCE  FOR  INCREASING  RESPONSIBILITIES 

Even  a  brief  survey  of  the  growth  of  public  administration  would  not  be 
complete  without  some  mention  of  the  advances  and  adjustments  which 
have  been  made  within  the  system  to  enable  it  to  handle  the  increasing  load 
it  has  had  to  carry.  Nor  can  we  leave  the  subject  without  some  appraisal  of 
government's  administrative  capacity  for  sustaining  the  burdens  likely  to 
be  thrust  upon  it  in  the  future.  Let  us,  therefore,  now  take  note  of  the  peren- 
nial struggle  that  has  been  waged  in  American  administration  for  competent 
personnel;  of  the  major  gains  registered  in  the  fields  of  administrative  struc- 
ture and  procedure;  of  the  effects  produced  and  problems  generated  by 
national  emergencies;  and  of  the  implications  for  public  administration  aris- 
ing from  the  expectations  of  the  American  people  themselves. 

Professional  Versus  Amateur.  Concerned  as  it  is  with  means  rather  than 
ends,  administration  is  a  phase  of  government  in  which  accomplishment  can 
be  measured  with  a  degree  of  objectivity.  It  is,  moreover,  a  phase  in  which 
it  is  possible  to  describe  with  relative  precision  the  particular  qualities  or 
abilities  which  individuals  ought  to  have  for  the  positions  to  which  they  may 
be  assigned.  It  might,  therefore,  be  supposed  that  a  system  could  have  been 
established  early  in  our  history  whereby  appointments  to  positions  in  the 
public  service  would  have  been  conditioned  upon  demonstration  of  the  skills 
or  talents  required  for  the  proper  performance  of  official  duties. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  21 

The  facts  do  not  bear  out  this  supposition.  Whether,  as  some  say,  because 
we  are  democratically  inclined,  or  because  of  other  reasons,  the  great  ma- 
jority of  the  American  people  have  always  had  a  pronounced  preference  for 
amateur  government.  Wanting  in  general  only  so  much  governance  as 
seemed  absolutely  necessary  to  take  care  of  recognized  public  interests  and 
concerns,  and  eager  to  keep  that  bare  minimum  securely  under  their  own 
control,  they  have  experimented  with  a  variety  of  arrangements  for  organiz- 
ing the  public  service.  One  device,  still  widely  used  in  state  and  local  govern- 
ment, is  that  of  placing  so  many  offices  on  an  elective  basis  that  the  electorate 
is  compelled — or,  according  to  the  logic  of  this  philosophy,  privileged — to 
choose  not  only  its  political  representatives  but  a  considerable  body  of  admin- 
istrative officials  as  well.  A  second  formula,  now  for  the  most  part  happily 
abandoned,  was  that  of  annual  elections,  based  on  the  theory  that  where 
short  terms  end,  tyranny  may  begin.  Rotation  in  office  comprised  a  third 
approach,  which  has  been  fraught  with  so  much  peril  to  efficiency  in  admin- 
istration that  it  warrants  speciaK^ittention. 

Washington  and  Adams,  the\  first  two  presidents  of  the  United  States, 
prided  themselves  on  being  goocf^  republicans  but  neither  claimed  to  be  a 
democrat  in  the  Jeffersonian  sense.  Believing  that  politics  and  administra- 
tion were  for  the  established  social  elite  of  their  day — "the  rich,  the  well- 
born, and  the  able" — they  pursued  personnel  policies  similar  to  those  of  the 
more  enlightened  prime  ministers  of  Britain  during  the  late  eighteenth 
century.  They  took  it  ,for  granted — as  did  also  John  Quincy  Adams  later — 
that  the  best  families  bf  the  country  should  and  would  inspire  their  ablest 
sons  to  seek  careers  in  the  government  service.  In  consequence,  they  had 
little  doubt  that  a  president  determined — as  both  of  them  were — to  draw 
into  the  public  service  men  of  talent  would  not  encounter  any  difficulty  in 
recruiting  and  retaining  an  able  and  devoted  staff. 

AHoVving  for  Jefferson's  deep  distrust  of  social  station,  his  inherent  inclina- 
tions wye  also  toward  "talent  and  virtue"  seeking  public  office;  so  were 
those  of  Madison  and  Monroe,  his  successors  in  the  White  House.  How- 
ever, following  his  election  in  1800,  Jefferson  discovered  that  two  practical 
considerations  obliged  him  to  dismiss  a  number  of  Federalist  appointees  and 
replace  them  with  Republicans.  One  was  the  inability  of  some  of  the  Fed- 
eralist holdovers  to  convince  Jefferson  that  they  could  be  depended  upon 
to  show  no  less  zeal  in  carrying  out  Republican  policies  than  they  had  in  the 
service  of  Washington  and  Adams.  The  other  was  the  pressure  for  posi- 
tions put  upon  the  new  President  by  members  of  his  own  party. 

Originally,  the  principle  of  rotation  in  office  was  virtually  limited  in 
practice  to  legislative  offices,  but  agitation  arose  early  in  the  history  of  the 
Union  for  its  application  to  administrative  offices  as  well.  Congress  adopted 
in  1820  the  famous  Four  Years  Law.  This  act  provided  that  federal  district 
attorneys,  collectors  of  customs,  naval  officers,  money  agents,  registrars  of 
land  offices,  paymasters  in  the  army,  and  several  other  classes  of  officials 


22  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

should  serve  four-year  terms  rather  than  at  the  pleasure  of  the  President, 
as  they  had  formerly.13  Even  without  this  law,  it  is  more  than  likely  that 
Andrew  Jackson  during  his  administration  (1829-1837)  would  have  man- 
aged to  dismiss  a  considerable  number  of  the  Whigs  he  found  in  the  executive 
branch  at  his  inauguration.  There  can  be  little  doubt,  however,  that  the  law 
helped  him  to  effect  those  changes  in  public  personnel  he  thought  necessary 
to  place  the  government  under  the  control  of  "the  people" — that  is,  those 
who  had  voted  him  into  office.  The  four-year  rule  was  later  modified;  but 
it  contributed  materially  to  the  establishment  of  the  spoils  system  in  the 
United  States.  For  half  a  century,  from  the  1830's  to  the  1880's,  the  over- 
whelming  majority  of  appointments  in  American  administration — national, 
state,  and  local — were  made  on  the  basis  of  party  patronage. 

Patronage  and  Economy.  During  the  early  decades  of  the  middle  1800's, 
the  functions  of  government  continued  to  be  limited  in  volume  and  relatively 
simple  in  character.  American  genius  for  muddling  along  being  not  inferior 
to  that  of  the  British,  it  was  possible  even  later  on  for  the  public  business 
to  be  transacted  tolerably  well  by  politically  selected  amateur  employees 
working  under  loose  organization  and  utilizing  casual  procedures.  But  that 
age  came  to  an  end.  After  the  Civil  War,  the  new  materialism  of  indus- 
trialization, economic  instability  and  insecurity,  the  loosening  of  personal 
ties  as  a  result  of  increasing  urbanization,  the  opportunities  for  graft  on  a 
grand  scale  latent  in  municipal  construction  and  utilities,  and  the  mounting 
necessity  for  professionally  trained  personnel  to  handle  the  new  technical 
functions  and  services  of  government — all  these  led  to  conditions  which 
made  reform  imperative. 

Disclosures  of  inefficiency  and  corruption  touching  every  level  of  admin- 
istration aroused  cities  and  states  and  the  nation  itself  to  a  reexami nation  of 
democracy  long  overdue.  Gradually  a  demand  emerged  for  the  establish- 
ment and  enforcement  of  higher  standards  of  official  competence  and  for 
tighter  procedures  wherever  public  moneys  or  properties  were  involved.14 
However,  indignation  over  ineptitude  or  wrongdoing  was  not  the  prime 
factor  in  the  imposition  of  new  controls.  Rather,  as  the  cost  of  government 
increased  with  additional  functions  of  a  technical  nature,  inefficient  adminis- 
tration led  to  disproportionately  heavier  taxation  which  the  public  could  less 
well  afford  to  ignore. 

In  national  administration,  the  milestones  marking  the  progress  of  reform 
were  the  Pendleton  Act  inaugurating  the  rule  of  merit  in  the  recruitment  of 
public  personnel  (1883);  the  expansion  of  the  new  civil  service  by  executive 

13  Sec  Fish,  Carl  Russell,  The  Civil  Service  and  the  Patronage,  p.  66,  Cambridge:   Harvard 
University  Press,  1920.    This  is  the  leading  study  of  the  history  of  national  personnel  policies 
and  practices  during  the  nineteenth  century. 

14  Cf.  StefTens,  Lincoln,  The  Struggle  for  Seif -Government,  New  York:   Doubleday,  1906, 
being  an  attempt  to  trace  American  political  corruption  to  its  sources  in  six  states  of  the  United 
States;    Foulke,    William   D.,    Fighting   the   Spoilsmen,   New   York:     Putnam,    1919;   Lynch, 
Dennis  T.,  Boss  Tweed,  New  York:    Boni  &  Liveright,  1927. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  23 

orders  under  Presidents  Cleveland  and  Wilson;  the  Classification  Act  initiat- 
ing a  more  uniform  position  structure  in  federal  employment  (1923);  the 
report  of  the  Commission  of  Inquiry  on  Public  Service  Personnel  (1935); 
and  the  report  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improvement 
chaired  by  Justice  Reed  (1941).  Corresponding  improvements  in  personnel 
administration  were  accomplished  within  their  own  jurisdictions  by  the 
more  progressive  states  and  cities. 

Advances  in  Structure  and  Procedure.  In  line  with  these  efforts  toward 
building  a  professionally  competent  and  politically  nonpartisan  civil  service 
have  been  equally  important  improvements  in  administrative  structure  and 
procedure.  Congress  on  several  occasions  took  action  in  the  interest  of  better 
administration.  It  gave  support  to  the  Commission  on  Economy  and  Effici- 
ency under  President  Taft  by  creation  of  a  Bureau  of  Efficiency  (1913-1933). 
It  greatly  enhanced  executive  control  over  the  departmental  system  and 
strengthened  fiscal  accountability  by  passing  the  Budget  and  Accounting 
Act  (1921).  By  giving  President  Roosevelt  a  measure  of  discretion  in  the 
Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  Congress  enabled  him,  just  before  the  outbreak 
of  World  War  II,  to  simplify  the  structure  of  the  executive  branch  and 
organize  his  own  office  in  line  with  the  recommendations  of  the  President's 
Committee  on  Administrative  Management.15  Similar  powers  were  granted 
in  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1945  in  order  to  adjust  the  wartime  develop- 
ment to  peacetime  needs. 

Under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  the  more  than  one  hundred  agen- 
cies of  the  federal  "administrative  branch"  were  for  the  most  part — excepting 
especially  the  so-called  independent  boards  and  commissions — regrouped 
into  the  ten  departments  and  three  new  combined  agencies  for  social  wel- 
fare, public  works,  and  public  lending.  Still  more  important,  the  President 
as  administrator-in-chief  was  buttressed  by  provision  for  several  administra- 
tive assistants  and  by  the  establishment  of  his  own  executive  office  in  which 
he  found  his  "arms  of  management"  for  budgeting,  planning,  and  per- 
sonnel. The  need  for  subsequent  innovations  was  recognized  in  the  creation 
of  an  Office  for  Emergency  Management  as  a  division  of  the  Executive 
Office  of  the  President.  Most  of  the  great  control  agencies  of  World  War  II 
were  nominally  placed  within  the  Office  for  Emergency  Management. 

Three  main  developments  symbolize  the  progress  made  in  raising  the 

15  No  official  publication  contains  more  valuable  material  on  American  public  administra- 
tion, whether  from  the  standpoint  of  analysis  or  information,  than  the  report  of  the  President's 
Committee  on  Administrative  Management  and  its  supporting  documents,  Washington,  Govern- 
ment Printing  Office,  1937.  Louis  Brownlow  served  as  chairman  of  the  President's  Committee, 
and  Charles  E.  Merriam  and  Luther  Gulick  were  its  other  two  members.  Although  Congress 
eventually  authorized  the  President  to  proceed  with  many  of  the  committee  recommendations, 
the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  at  the  same  time  imposed  considerable  restrictions.  Because 
of  the  "great  debate"  among  the  experts  over  the  auditing  function,  one  should  read,  along 
with  the  Brownlow  Report,  the  report  of  the  Brookings  Institution  to  the  Senate  Committee 
(Senator  Byrd,  chairman)  set  up  to  investigate  the  executive  agencies  of  the  federal  government, 
Senate  Report  No.  1275,  75th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1937, 


24  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

level  of  efficiency  in  state  administration.  Beginning  with  Illinois  under  the 
leadership  of  Governor  Frank  O.  Lowden  in  1917,  approximately  half  the 
states  in  the  Union  have  taken  action  to  unify  their  administrative  organi- 
zation under  the  governor.  Most  of  the  states  have  also  been  obliged  to  give 
special  consideration  to  the  caliber  of  management  attained  by  particular 
state  departments  in  order  to  qualify  for  the  increasing  number  of  grants-m- 
aid available  from  the  national  government.  Lastly,  the  states  have  begun 
to  make  it  a  practice,  chiefly  through  the  Council  of  State  Governments,16 
to  exchange  information  and  experience  on  all  kinds  of  administrative  prob- 
lems. 

The  principal  improvements  in  local  administration  relate,  on  the  whole, 
either  to  various  phases  of  municipal  affairs  or  to  public  education.  In  the 
field  of  urban  government,  they  include  the  formation  in  1894  of  the  National 
Municipal  League;  the  strengthening  in  many  mayor-council  cities  of  the 
appointive  and  directive  powers  of  the  mayor;  the  impulse  given  to  better 
municipal  management,  chiefly  during  the  decade  from  1905  to  1915,  by  the 
novel  commission  form  of  city  government;  the  movement  for  organized 
municipal  research  which  started  with  the  establishment  of  the  New  York 
Bureau  of  Municipal  Research  in  1906;  the  widespread  drive,  commencing 
more  than  a  generation  ago,  for  the  introduction  of  systematic  methods  of 
municipal  budgeting  and  purchasing;  the  growth  of  the  council-manager 
plan  of  city  government  in  the  wake  of  agitation  for  the  commission  plan; 
and  the  formation  over  the  past  three  or  four  decades  of  national  profes- 
sional associations  of  all  major  groups  of  local  administrative  officials,  culmi- 
nating in  the  establishment  in  1931  of  the  Public  Administration  Clearing 
House,  which  at  1313  East  60th  Street  in  Chicago  has  become  an  unofficial 
capitol  for  state  and  local  administration  throughout  the  country.17 

Three  lines  of  advance,  again,  describe  the  progress  in  educational  admin- 
istration. These  are  the  well-nigh  universal  development  of  the  superin- 
tendent of  schools  into  the  chief  administrative  officer  of  the  local  school 
system;  the  formation  of  the  National  Education  Association  and  other 
professional  organizations;  and,  finally,  the  movement  for  school  districts 
both  large  enough  in  pupil  population  and  strong  enough  in  financial  re- 
sources to  operate  programs  conforming  to  acceptable  minimum  instruc- 
tion standards.  No  substantial  improvement  can  thus  far  be  registered  for 
rural  administration  in  general.  This  is  probably  due  to  the  fact  that,  as 
some  of  the  more  important  rural  functions  were  partially  shouldered  by  the 
state,  the  county  continued  to  give  reasonably  satisfactory  service. 

16  The  publication  program  of  the  Council  of  State  Governments  includes  the  magazine 
State  Government  and  a  periodically  issued  handbook  entitled  The  Boo%  of  the  States. 

17  Aside   from    such    sources   of   current   information    about   local    administration   as   the 
National  Municipal  Review  (published  by  the  National  Municipal  League),  the  monthly  Public 
Management,  and  The  Municipal  Yearbook  (both  put  out  by  the  International  City  Managers 
Association),  mention  should  be  made  of  the  official  organs  of  thr  various  functional  asso- 
ciations within  and  without  the  "1313"  group. 


THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  25 

Impact  of  Emergencies.  As  tragedy  is  the  test  of  character  in  personal 
life,  so  crisis  is  the  test  of  capacity  iri  administration.  Accumulation  of 
abuses  in  both  public  and  private  areas  threatened  to  produce  a  partial  gov- 
ernmental crisis  in  the  United  States  during  the  decade  preceding  the  open- 
ing of  World  War  I.  It  was  largely  forestalled  by  a  series  of  reforms 
embodied  in  what  Theodore  Roosevelt  liked  to  call  his  Square  Deal,  by 
Taft's  adherence  to  "T.  R.'s"  trust-busting  program,  and  more  fully  by  the 
measures  adopted  as  a  result  of  Woodrow  Wilson's  campaign  for  the  New 
Freedom.  However,  the  coming  of  World  War  I,  particularly  America's 
entrance  into  the  conflict,  put  the  nation's  resources  in  public  administra- 
tion to  a  substantial  test.  The  country  was  required  on  short  notice  to  draft 
and  train  a  vast  army,  produce  enormous  quantities  of  food  and  war  ma- 
terials, and  raise  billions  of  dollars  in  loans  and  taxes.  The  measure  of  suc- 
cess achieved  may  be  taken  from  the  subsequent  appraisal  by  the  vanquished 
enemy,  "They  knew  how  to  wage  war."  Yet  World  War  I  had  only  one 
significant  permanent  effect  on  public  administration:  the  executive  branch 
never  returned  to  its  prewar  dimensions  either  from  the  standpoint  of  the 
number  of  agencies  and  government  employees  or  that  of  its  over-all  size. 

The  impact  upon  public  administration  of  the  Great  Depression  was 
more  momentous  because  many  of  the  measures  taken  to  cope  with  it  were 
looked  upon  as  presaging  profound  changes  in  the  "American  system"  or 
the  national  "way  of  life."  Moreover,  the  economic  crisis  affected  every  level 
of  government  and  nearly  every  community,  urban  and  rural,  throughout 
the  country.  The  emergency  called  for  a  vast  enlargement  of  the  nation's 
administrative  machine  and  for  the  exercise  of  new  powers  pointing  in  the 
direction  of  greater  governmental  responsibility  for  the  maintenance  of  the 
social  and  economic  structure.  Demanding  closer  collaboration  between 
Washington  and  the  states,  between  the  states  and  the  localities,  and  between 
the  localities  and  Washington,  the  emergency  also  forced  something  of  a 
transformation  within  the  American  governmental  system.  Competitive 
federalism  began  to  yield  by  degrees  to  cooperative  federalism. 

How  far  these  changes  went  and  what  their  permanent  effects  were 
destined  to  be  are  questions  to  which  there  are  no  precise  answers.  World 
War  II  overtook  the  United  States  before  the  nation  had  pulled  itself  com- 
pletely out  of  the  pit.  Instead  of  shrinking  in  size  or  authority,  govern- 
ment was  vested  with  greater  powers  and  obliged  to  expand  its  activities 
and  personnel  beyond  any  precedent.  The  end  of  the  war  allowed  consid- 
erable reductions,  but  under  the  auspices  of  a  policy  of  high-level  employ- 
ment we  may  expect  the  role  of  government  to  remain  an  extremely  impor- 
tant factor  in  support  of  national  prosperity  and  well-being. 

Tas{s  of  Administration  in  Mid-Century.  America  in  the  middle  twen- 
tieth century  will  not  and  can  not  return  to  the  old  order,  be  it  that  of 
1929  or  1939.  No  nation  can  safely  go  back;  ours  does  not  want  to  go  back. 
The  memory  of  insecurity  and  unemployment  lingering  on  from  the  late 


26  THE  GROWTH  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

1930's  and  the  knowledge  of  greatly  increased  productive  capacity  developed 
during  World  War  II  have  combined  to  make  Americans  reject  a  mere 
"return  to  normalcy."  They  want  a  world  in  which  a  strong  international 
organization  can  and  will  prevent  war.  And  such  international  organization 
has  implications  for  American  public  administration.  The  people  also  want 
"full  employment."  Their  determination  to  attain  stable  employment  means 
that  in  the  period  ahead  public  administration  may  be  asked  to  carry  bur- 
dens harder  and  heavier  than  those  it  has  ever  carried  during  the  past. 

The  American  economy  is  today  a  mixed  economy — a  blending  of  pri- 
vate and  public  undertakings.  This  interlocking  calls  for  wise  public  policy 
and  sensitive  administration.  The  public  is  looking  to  government  for 
assurance  that  the  national  economy  will  be  kept  operating  at  high  levels 
of  production  and  employment.  This  requires  governmental  guidance  in 
fiscal  policy  and  carefully  planned  adjustments  at  many  points  of  the 
economy.18  Here  is  a  challenging  mandate  for  responsible  administration, 
but  one  that  can  be  met  as  unparalleled  war  needs  have  been  met. 

As  the  nation  approaches  mid-century,  the  crucial  question  is  not  whether 
its  public  administration  will  be  adequate  and  efficient,  but  whether  its 
governmental  policies  will  be  sound  and  enlightened.  The  danger  is  not 
that  we  might  adopt  plans  and  programs  so  ambitious  that  government 
would  be  unable  to  find  administrators  capable  of  their  execution.  Rather 
it  is  that  cleavage  and  confusion  among  the  people,  fostered  by  selfish 
groups  bent  only  on  their  special  interest,  might  destroy  the  common  basis 
on  which  elected  representatives  could  agree  on  a  constructive  policy  for  the 
promotion  of  the  general  welfare. 

18  Cf.  Morstun  Marx,  Fritz,  eel.,  "Maintaining  High-Level  Production  and  Employment: 
A  Symposium,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  pp.  1119-1179. 


X  X  X  X-  X *********************  ************** ************** 


CHAPTER 


The  Study  of  Public  Administration 

1.  THE  WORK  OF  THE  PIONEERS 

Beginnings  of  Administrative  Research.  Public  administration  empha- 
sizes the  value  of  the  contributions  in  executing  public  policy  of  men  and 
women  who,  through  experience  or  study,  have  developed  a  considerable 
degree  of  skill  in  the  administrative  process.  This  process  includes:  the 
designing  of  appropriate  administrative  structures  and  the  organizing  of 
their  component  units;  the  formulating  of  work  programs,  standards  of 
performance,  and  ways  of  measuring  results;  the  budgeting  of  public  rev- 
enue and  expenditures  and  the  accounting  for  funds;  the  recruiting,  train- 
ing, and  directing  of  a  suitable  staff;  the  assumption  of  responsibility  for  the 
conduct  of  operations  on  the  one  hand  and  for  planning  proposed  policy 
changes  on  the  other;  and  the  making  of  proper  arrangements  for  the  con- 
duct of  relations  with  other  administrative  agencies,  the  legislature,  private 
individuals,  organized  groups,  and  the  general  public.1 

Consideration  of  these  various  elements  may  suggest  the  existence  of  an 
extensive  body  of  cumulative  experience,  study,  and  analysis.  However, 
as  an  organized  field  of  knowledge,  public  administration  in  the  United 
States  is  only  forty  years  old,  if  its  birth  date  is  accepted  as  1906,  the  year 
the  New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research  was  established.2  Creation  of 
the  New  York  Bureau  symbolized  the  beginning  of  a  profession  and  a 
science  of  administration  in  three  essential  respects:  accumulation  of 
descriptive  materials  about  the  purposes,  powers,  structure,  and  functioning 
of  governmental  agencies;  application  of  analytical  techniques  and  techni- 
cal standards;  and  employment  of  a  full-time  expert  staff,  prepared  to  accept 

1  For  a  full  discussion  of  the  range  and  the  elements  of  the  administrative  process  in  this 
sense,  see  Gaus,  John  M.  and  Others,  The  Frontiers  of  Public  Administration,  ch.  1,  Chicago: 
University  of  Chicago  Press,  1936;  Gulick,  Luther  and  Urwick,  Lyndall,  cds.,  Papers  on  the 
Science  of  Administration,  New  York:    Institute  of  Public  Administration,  1937. 

2  See  Weber,  G.  A.,  Organized  Efforts  for  the  Improvement  of  Methods  in  Administration, 
Introduction    (by   W.   F.   Willoughby)    and   ch.    1,   Washington:    Institute   for  Government 
Research,  1919. 

27 


28  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

responsibility  for  recommending  specific  measures  for  the  improvement  of 
administrative  organization  and  management.  For  more  than  ten  years 
the  New  York  Bureau  made  studies  and  reports  covering  almost  all  the 
municipal  activities  of  the  city.  Its  methods  of  establishing  working  rela- 
tionships with  the  city  government,  of  developing  productive  opportunities 
for  investigation,  and  of  getting  its  recommendations  adopted  not  only 
constituted  the  earliest  American  experience  in  continuing  administrative 
research  but  also  set  a  prototype  for  use  throughout  the  country.3 

Waves  of  Government  Reform.  The  research-bureau  movement,  of 
course,  did  not  materialize  suddenly  out  of  thin  air.  It  developed  after  a 
period  of  more  than  twenty  years  of  political  agitation  and  experimentation 
with  political  "reform."  Most  of  the  reformers  were  people  who,  though 
unwilling  or  unable  to  go  into  politics  themselves,  thought  that  the  political 
life  of  the  nation  should  be  purified  and  that  "better"  men  should  enter 
public  service.  The  reformers  included  such  advocates  of  the  merit  system 
in  government  employment  as  Carl  Schurz  and  Dorman  B.  Eaton;  jour 
nalists  and  publicists  like  E.  L.  Godkin,  Henry  Adams,  and  Henry  Dem- 
arest  Lloyd;  and  practical  businessmen,  lawyers,  clergymen,  teachers,  and 
other  citizens  who  organized  city  clubs  to  promote  "good  government." 
These  individuals  and  civic-minded  groups  left  a  lasting  legacy  in  the 
formation  and  the  working  approach  of  our  civil  service  commissions,  and 
other  devices  of  reform.  Their  political  activities  were  less  successful.  Al- 
though they  helped  to  elect  "good"  candidates  to  office  in  many  cities, 
usually  these  men  were  voted  out  soon  and  the  party  bosses  came  back  into 
power.  Lacking  broad  sympathetic  support,  the  independent  civil  service 
commissions  were  in  such  instances  often  controlled  or  isolated  by  partisan 
forces. 

Thoughtful  analysis  of  these  experiences  resulted,  around  the  turn  of 
the  century,  in  several  more  or  less  systematic  inquiries  into  the  facts  of 
governmental  life.  One  form  of  governmental  research  was  represented  by 
the  brilliant  newspaper  and  magazine  reports  of  the  "muckrakers,"  whose 
exposure  of  the  deeper  economic  roots  of  political  corruption  had  a  wide  if 
short-lived  influence.4  Characteristic  realism  and  a  propensity  for  quick 
generalization  led  these  writers  to  take  the  simple  position  that  the  economic 
system  controlled  the  politicians;  that  the  politicians  controlled  civil  service 
commissions  and  operating  officials;  and  that  the  remainder  of  public 
administration,  insofar  as  it  was  not  dishonest  or  corrupt,  was  simply  the 
unimportant  routine  execution  of  public  business. 

Organized  Dissemination  of  Knowledge.  Another  type  of  research  ex- 
pressed itself  in  the  collection  and  dissemination  of  information  on  munici- 

3  See  Gill,  Norman  N.,  Municipal  Research  Bureaus,  Washington:  American  Council  on 
Public  Affairs,  1942. 

4Stefrens,  Lincoln,  Autobiography,  New  York:  Harcourt  Brace,  1931;  Whitlock,  Brand, 
Forty  Years  of  It,  New  York:  Appleton,  new  ed.,  1925;  and  the  autobiographies  of  Robert  M. 
LaFollcttc,  Sr.,  and  Theodore  Roosevelt. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  29 

pal  facts  and  events  by  the  National  Municipal  League,  founded  in  1894, 
and  the  formulation  by  chat  body  after  1900  of  its  standard  "model  laws" 
for  the  organization  and  powers  of  local  and  state  governments.  The 
research  activities  of  the  League  and  the  more  active  promotional  tactics 
of  its  offshoot,  the  National  Short  Ballot  Organization,  were  of  great  assist- 
ance to  the  developing  profession  of  public  administration.  On  the  whole, 
however,  these  and  similar  private  organizations  concentrated  on  reporting 
developments  in  better  government  structure  and  the  framing  of  charters, 
ordinances,  and  constitutions.  They  tended  to  leave  the  study  and  im- 
provement of  administrative  management,  processes,  and  standards  to 
"technicians."5 

Role  of  Progressivism.  A  third  type  of  governmental  research  was  asso- 
ciated between  1S%  and  1912  with  the  political  movement  called  Progres- 
sivism. Progressivism  has  often  been  identified  with  the  personalities  of 
its  leaders.0  One  common  bond  between  them  was  the  conviction  that  if 
new  policies  of  economic  regulation  were  to  be  made  to  stick,  those  policies 
must  be  removed  from  the  hands  of  legislative  bodies  and  administered  by 
expert  boards  on  the  basis  of  technical  investigation  and  nonpolitical  deter- 
mination of  the  facts.  Early  systematic  thinking  about  the  independent 
regulatory  commission  was  linked  with  Progressivism  in  the  states,  and  in 
at  least  one  state,  Wisconsin,  it  was  based  on  close  collaboration  between 
the  state  capitol  and  the  state  university.  This  collaboration  made  pos- 
sible in  1901  the  establishment  of  one  of  the  first  legislative  reference  libraries 
in  the  United  States.  It  also  paved  the  way  for  considerable  research  and 
participation  by  university  professors  in  the  drafting  of  state  legislation. 
The  ensuing  period  witnessed  the  initial  establishment  in  many  states  of 
effective  legislation  regulating  public  utilities,  workmen's  compensation, 
conservation  of  natural  resources,  and  conditions  of  employment. 

If  the  trends  inherent  in  the  progressive  movement  prior  to  1912  had 
continued,  perhaps  the  study  of  public  administration  would  have  developed 
on  a  subject-matter  basis,  as  separate  scries  of  professional  or  expert  tech- 
niques, each  peculiar  to  a  distinct  area  of  economic  policy.  What  actually 
happened,  however,  was  something  different.  Development  of  the  theory 
of  the  administrative  process  exemplified  by  the  independent  regulatory 
commission  was  largely  taken  over  by  the  economists  and  lawyers,  while 
the  political  scientists  divided  themselves  into  two  groups.  One  group  busied 
itself  with  structural  problems  in  the  relations  between  the  federal  govern- 

5  For  a  valuable  survey,  see  the  Fiftieth  Anniversary  Issue  of  the  National  Municipal 
Review,  November  1944. 

<*  Cf.  Croly,  Herbert,  Progressive  Democracy,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1915,  which  is  perhaps 
the  best  statement  of  i's  political  program.  See  also  Chamberlain,  John,  Farewell  to  Reform, 
New  York:  Viking,  1933;  Bowers,  C.  G.,  Beveridge  and  the  Progressive  Era,  Boston:  Hough  ton 
Mifflin,  1932.  Progressivism  was  really  faith  in  a  method,  rather  than  a  coherent  philosophy 
or  economic  program,  coupled  with  an  abiding  belief  that  the  people  would  support  expert 
administration  if  properly  led  and  given  the  facts  by  responsible  political  leaders. 


30  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

ment  and  the  states,  state  control  over  local  government,  political  executives 
and  the  legislative  body,  and  the  proper  organization  of  the  executive 
branch.  The  other  joined  forces  with  the  municipal  research-bureau  move- 
ment in  the  conviction  that  progress  toward  good  government  would  follow 
only  from  full-time  detailed  study  and  technical  analysis  of  the  methods  of 
conducting  the  government's  business. 

Contribution  of  the  Universities.  The  contribution  of  the  universities  to 
the  rise  of  public  administration  was  rather  indirect,  with  the  exception  of  a 
few  outstanding  individuals.  Woodrow  Wilson  contributed  his  pioneer 
paper  entitled  "The  Study  of  Administration"  to  the  infant  Political  Science 
Quarterly  in  1887.  James  Bryce  is  said  to  have  drawn  heavily  upon  the 
series  of  Johns  Hopkins  studies  in  historical  and  political  science  (beginning 
in  1882),  as  well  as  upon  the  services  of  Professor  Frank  J.  Goodnow,  in 
preparing  his  influential  American  Commonwealth  (1888).  Many  students 
of  Simon  Patten  at  the  University  of  Pennsylvania,  Richard  T.  Ely  and 
John  R.  Commons  at  Johns  Hopkins  and  Wisconsin,  A.  L.  Lowell  at 
Harvard,  and  of  the  faculty  of  History,  Government,  and  Public  Law  at 
Columbia  University,  later  distinguished  themselves  in  the  practice  and 
literature  of  public  administration.  However,  during  the  earlier  period  the 
study  of  government  and  politics  was  just  disentangling  itself  in  the  college 
curriculum  from  philosophy,  political  economy,  and  a  jurisprudence  domi- 
nated by  the  private  law  of  property.7 

The  academic  progenitors  of  public  administration  in  the  eighties  and 
nineties  were  economists,  political  scientists,  and  sociologists  who  taught 
their  students  how  to  analyze  the  economic  and  political  processes  through 
which  public  authority  is  exercised,  without  much  speculating  about  the 
concepts  of  political  philosophers  and  supreme  court  judges.  Even  so, 
legal  materials  constituted  so  much  of  the  subject  matter  with  which  stu- 
dents of  government  dealt  in  those  days  that  Goodnow,  who  is  generally 
considered  the  father  of  American  public  administration,  wrote  most  of  his 
books  in  the  fields  of  administrative  and  constitutional  law.8  If  it  is  con- 
ceded that  a  true  profession  of  public  administration  could  not  have  arisen 
until  after  trained  men  began  to  study  at  first  hand  the  working  processes 
of  government,  then  contemporary  students  surely  owe  to  their  academic 
forefathers  a  large  debt  for  their  critical  and  realistic  temper,  their  aware- 

7  See  Beard,  Charles  A.,  Economic  Interpretation  of  the  Constitution,  Introduction,  New 
York:    Macmillan,  rev.  ed.,   1932;  Dorfman,  Joseph,  Thorstein  Veblen  and  His  America,  esp. 
chs.  3-6,  New  York:    Viking,  1934;  Merriam,  Charles  E.,  American  Political  Ideas  1865-1917, 
New  York:   Macmillan,  1920. 

8  See  Fairlie,  John  A.,  "Public  Administration  and  Administrative  Law,"  ch.  1,  in  Haines, 
Charles  G.  and  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  cds.,  Essays  on  the  Law  and  Practice  of  Governmental 
Administration,  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1935. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  31 

ness  of  the  institutional  determinants  of  public  policy,  and  their  distrust  of 
the  legalistic  approach.9 

2.  THE  ADVANCEMENT  OF  KNOWLEDGE 

Relativity  of  Efficiency.  Full-time  research  bureaus  were  established 
in  twelve  large  cities  between  1906  and  1915.  Their  slogan  was  efficiency 
and  economy.  The  experience  of  their  staffs  in  administrative  research 
soon  revealed  the  fugitive  nature  of  this  objective,  when  conceived  as 
a  source  of  immediate  reduction  in  governmental  expenditure.  It  was  dis- 
covered that  efficiency  and  economy  had  to  be  achieved  primarily  as  a 
by-product  of  getting  at  the  basic  facts  of  administrative  purpose,  structure, 
and  procedure.  Leaving  out  instances  of  outright  venality  and  political 
privilege,  it  was  found  that  there  was  always  a  certain  degree  of  efficiency 
in  existing  methods  and  routines.  Apart  from  the  question  of  whether  a 
given  function  should  or  should  not  be  performed,  the  goal  of  efficiency 
and  economy  raised  the  question  of  purpose — that  is,  whether  procedures 
were  to  be  considered  from  the  limited  standpoint  of  particular  operators 
and  particular  interests  or  from  that  of  the  public  purpose  the  individual 
agency  was  supposed  to  achieve.  Thus  research-bureau  workers  were  led  to 
a  search  for  principles  of  management  in  order  to  secure  acceptance  for 
those  practices  which  advanced  the  purpose  of  the  organization  as  a  whole, 
as  compared  with  procedures  and  habits  which  had  grown  up  for  historic 
reasons  or  had  been  established  by  operators  with  narrower  objectives  in 
view. 

For  example,  from  the  angle  of  a  municipal  department  head,  it  might 
be  preferable  to  go  directly  to  the  city  council  for  funds.  Broader  perspec- 
tive would  be  necessary  for  him  to  envision  the  advantages  of  budgetary 
coordination  at  a  central  point.  Yet  only  thus  could  a  balanced  consideration 
of  the  work  plan  of  the  city  government  as  a  whole  be  attained  before 
submitting  the  estimates  of  expenditure  to  the  council.  In  the  same  way, 
individual  officials  did  not  mind  the  scattering  of  similar  functions  among 
several  agencies  and  the  existence  of  varying  methods  of  performing  similar 
operations  by  different  organizations.  Yet  there  was  obvious  merit  in  the 
principle  that  functional  consolidation  and  establishment  of  uniform  stand- 
ards be  secured  in  the  larger  interest,  even  at  the  expense  of  particular  offi- 

9  Organizations  of  public  officials  such  as  state  and  local  health  officers,  police  chiefs, 
superintendents  of  insurance,  and  tax  and  educational  administrators  existed  before  1906. 
These  early  organizations  were  in  many  cases  more  social  groups  than  promoters  of  research 
in  the  standards  of  their  profession,  however;  and  they  were  separatist  and  vocational  in 
interest.  See  White,  Leonard  D.,  Introduction  to  the  Study  of  Public  Administration,  ch.  27, 
New  York:  Macmillan,  rev.  ed.,  1939,  and  Trends  in  Public  Administration,  chs.  20,  22, 
New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1933.  Earlier  events  and  personalities  in  the  literature  of  public 
administration  are  discussed  in  Gaus,  John  M.,  A  Memorandum  on  Research  in  Public  Ad- 
ministration, Social  Science  Research  Council,  1930,  unpublished;  Short,  Lloyd  M.,  The 
Development  of  National  Administrative  Organization  in  the  United  States,  Washington: 
Institute  of  Government  Research,  1923. 


32  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

cials  who  might  have  achieved  considerable  efficiency  within  their  own 
operations.  Economy  was  not  simply  a  matter  of  eliminating  functions 
or  services,  most  of  which  were  ardently  supported  by  citizen  groups,  but 
one  of  giving  proper  consideration  to  the  specific  question  of  whether 
particular  expenditures  were  or  were  not  justified. 

Use  of  Outside  Experts.  Thus  administrative  research  tried  to  develop 
principles  and  techniques .  of  public  management.  The  executive  budget, 
personnel  classification  and  salary  standardization,  and  centralized  pur- 
chasing all  found  systematic  application  and  expansion  in  local  governments 
in  the  decade  following  1906.10  It  was  wholly  natural  that  Dr.  Frederick 
A.  Cleveland  of  the  New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research  was  ap- 
pointed by  President  Taft  in  1910  to  direct  the  work  of  the  United  States 
Commission  on  Economy  and  Efficiency.  The  Commission  and  its  staff 
for  the  first  time  applied  to  the  entire  executive  branch  of  the  federal  govern- 
ment the  full  measure  of  painstaking  research  into  administrative  duties,  or- 
ganization, procedure,  and  housekeeping  methods,  exhibiting  in  a  long  series 
of  factual  monographs  the  results  of  detailed  legislative  control  over  the  de- 
partments. In  his  final  report,  Dr.  Cleveland  formulated  what  is  perhaps 
the  classic  statement  of  the  purpose  of  the  executive  budget  as  a  scientific  tool 
of  administration,11  a  contribution  which  laid  an  early  foundation  for  the 
Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921.  Similarly,  the  Congressional  Joint 
Commission  on  Reclassification  of  Salaries  drew  heavily  upon  the  experience 
of  the  local  research  bureaus  in  their  work  of  job  description  and  classifica- 
tion; on  that  foundation  was  built  the  scheme  embodied  in  the  Classification 
Act  of  1923 — a  guidepost  for  federal  personnel  administration.1" 

The  drive  for  administrative  reorganization  of  state  governments  began 
in  1909.  Staff  work  and  reports  in  preparation  for  the  New  York  and  Illi- 
nois Constitutional  Conventions  of  1915  and  1917  were  notable  especially 
for  the  quality  and  method  of  research.13  These  reports  documented  three 
early  premises  of  organizational  thinking:  (1)  concentration  of  responsibility 
by  consolidating  functions  into  a  small  number  of  departments,  each  headed 
by  a  single  official  appointed  by  and  responsible  solely  to  the  chief  executive; 
(2)  functional  integration  by  grouping  similar  or  related  activities  into  the 
same  department;  and  (3)  centralized  controls  over  finance,  government 
purchasing,  and  personnel.  Executive  responsibility  for  administration  was 
the  dominating  theme.  Coupled  with  the  short  ballot,  the  executive  budget, 

i«  Cf.   White,  Trends  (cit.  in  note  9),  pp.  218-223,  255-257. 

11  "The  Need  for  a  National   Budget,"   62nd  Cong.,  2nd  Sess.,  House  Doc.  No.  854, 
Washington,  1912.   Cf.  also  his  Organized  Democracy,  New  York:   Macmillan,  1913. 

12  Sec   66th  Cong.,  2nd  Sess.,  House  Doc.  No.   686,  Washington,   1920.    Cf.  also  Per- 
sonnel   Classification    Board,    Closing   Report   of    Wage   and   Personnel   Survey,   Washington: 
Government  Printing  Office,  1931. 

13  Cf.    Buck,  A.  E.,  The  Reorganization  of  State  Governments  in  the  United  States,  New 
York:    Columbia  University  Press,  1938;  Holcombe,  Arthur  N.,  State  Government,  New  York: 
Macmillan,  3d  ed.,  1931;  New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research,  New  Yor%  State  Constitution 
wd  Government:   An  Appraisal,  New  York,  1915. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  33 

and  application  of  the  merit  system  to  all  but  politically  appointed  depart- 
ment heads,  these  main  propositions  conceived  as  principles  were  applied 
with  variations  in  about  half  the  states  between  1917  and  1932.  Many  of 
the  changes  were  based  upon  recommendations  derived  from  surveys  by 
three  private  organizations  staffed  with  specialists  in  administrative  analysis: 
the  Institute  of  Government  Research  of  the  Brookings  Institution  (Wash- 
ington), the  National  Institute  of  Public  Administration  (successor  to  the 
New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research),  and  Griffenhagen  and  Associ- 
ates (Chicago).  Their  surveys  usually  resulted  in  thorough,  factual  reports, 
with  recommendations  based  on  intensive  analyses  and  classifications  of 
activities  into  major  functions.  Such  reports  were  filed  with  the  governors 
or  legislative  bodies  for  appropriate  action.14 

Entirely  aside  from  the  general  rule  that  the  professional  staffs  of  investi- 
gators were  to  take  no  active  part  in  getting  their  recommendations  adopted, 
the  principles  recommended  in  most  of  the  state  surveys  came  in  for  quite  a 
bit  of  criticism.  It  was  questioned  whether  the  political  executive  would 
have  the  time  or  inclination  to  become  a  general  manager  for  administra- 
tion. The  notion  that  the  voters  would  ever  choose  their  mayors,  governors, 
or  presidents  on  the  basis  of  administrative  competence  was  ridiculed.  Doubts 
were  raised  as  to  whether  the  political  head  should  be  entrusted  with  author- 
ity over  all  finance  and  personnel  matters.  Finally,  instances  were  pointed 
out  in  which  there  were  persuasive  reasons  for  preferring  administrative 
boards  over  single-headed  agencies.17'  This  debate  revealed  the  confusion 
and  ambiguity  of  concepts  and  of  scientific  methods  that  had  crept  into  the 
thinking  of  students  of  public  administration.16 

Challenge  to  Traditional  Approach.  By  assuming  a  separation  of  policy- 
making  from  administrative  efficiency,  the  investigators  had  tried  to  arrive 
at  valid  principles,  at  least  on  the  technical  level  of  operations.  However, 
validity  of  principles  depends  upon  agreement:  (1)  on  the  diagnosis  of  the 
problem;  and  (2)  on  the  objective  sought  by  the  investigators.  The  argu- 

14  The   capstone  of   this   kind   of  outside  survey   work,  in  method  and  result,  was  the 
monumental  study  of  the  entire  area  of  federal  administration  by  the  Brookings  Institution  for 
the  Senate   (Byrd)   Committee  Investigating  Executive  Agencies,  75th  Cong.,   1st  Sess.,  Senate 
Report  No.  1275,  Washington,  1937. 

15  See  Hyncman,  Charles  S.,  "Administrative  Reorganization:    An  Adventure  into  Science 
and   Theology,"  Journal  of  Politics,   1939,  Vol.   1,  p.  62  ff.\  Walker,  Harvey,  "Theory  and 
Practice  in  State  Administrative  Reorganization,"  National  Municipal  Review,  1930,  Vol.  19, 
p.  249  jf.',  Coker,  Francis  W.,  "Dogmas  of  Administrative  Reform,"  American  Political  Science 
Review,  1922,  Vol.  16,  p.  399  ff. 

10  See  Beard,  Charles  A.,  "Administration:  A  Test  of  Ideal  and  Power,"  ch.  10,  in  his 
Public  Policy  and  General  Weljarc,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1941.  The  best  survey 
and  analysis  of  the  literature  of  public  administration  from  a  methodological  standpoint  is 
Waldo,  C.  Dwight,  Theoretical  Aspects  of  the  American  Literature  of  Public  Administration,  un- 
published Ph.D.  thcsii  at  Yale  University,  1942,  esp.  pp.  82-92  (scheduled  for  early  publication). 
Cf.  also  Wallace,  Scnuyler  C.,  Federal  Departmentalization ,  New  York:  Columbia  University 
Press,  1941;  Simon,  Herbert  A..  "The  Proverbs  of  Administration,"  Public  Administration 
Review,  1946,  Vol.  6,  p.  53  ff. 


34  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

ments  over  state  reorganization  in  the  1920's  foreshadowed  the  famous 
conflict  in  1937  and  1938  between  the  President's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Management  and  the  Brookings  Institution.  Both  situations  illus- 
trate the  degree  to  which  broad  agreement  upon  a  great  many  concrete 
propositions  for  administrative  improvement  can  be  distorted  by  differences 
over  the  priority  of  problems  and  by  the  intrusion  of  political  issues  and  value 
judgments  which  may  or  may  not  be  relevant  to  specific  proposals.  The  Pres- 
ident's Committee  eschewed  the  survey  method  of  functional  analysis  and 
classification  which  the  Brookings  Institution  had  utilized;  it  selected  its  ob- 
jectives in  terms  of  the  problems  conceived  by  its  sponsor  and  his  advisers 
to  be  of  compelling  importance.  Both  its  investigations  and  its  recom- 
mendations sought  to  develop  answers  to  these  problems. 

The  1937-1938  debates  have  caused  most  students  of  administration  to 
recast  their  notions  of  public  management  as  a  science  of  "principles." 
The  conception  of  the  scientific  investigator — one  standing  apart  from  his 
material  of  human  beings  while  making  his  inquiries;  collecting,  sifting, 
testing,  and  weighing  his  facts  and  ultimately  arriving  at  the  most  reliable 
conclusions — has  somehow  been  found  problematical  in  governmental  re- 
search. It  was  based  in  part  upon  Frederick  W.  Taylor's  ideas  of  scientific 
management,17  which  called  for  the  study  and  formulation  of  the  proper 
methods  of  job  performance  in  advance,  followed  by  adjustment  of  the 
human  factor  to  those  methods.  This  approach  or  technique  was  de- 
veloped and  applied  to  the  details  of  specific  job  operations  at  the 
shop  level  by  a  trained  engineer  or  superintendent  within  the  factory 
hierarchy  with  authority  over  the  workers.  It  lacks  applicability  to  man- 
agement research  into  program  questions.  Conditions  are  different  when  the 
research  staff  is  wholly  outside  the  hierarchy  of  responsibility  and  has 
no  powers  or  sanctions  over  the  human  element  other  than  publicity  and 
persuasion.  The  same  is  true  when  the  purpose  of  analysis  is  not  to  improve 
job  performance,  but  to  achieve  proper  structural  relationships.  A  different 
condition  also  prevails  when  the  objective  of  study  is  not  to  help  the  operat- 
ing official  do  a  better  job,  but  rather  is  to  change  his  job.  Moreover,  al- 
though being  outside  the  government  has  certain  advantages  of  freedom 
and  public  pressure,  it  presents  extremely  difficult  problems  in  developing 
and  maintaining  working  contacts  with  operating  officials.  Publicity  is  a 
one-shot  weapon  which,  when  improperly  used,  may  result  in  the  destruction 
of  working  relationships. 

Rise  of  Administrative  Self -Analysis.    Two  main  developments  have 

17  Taylor's  main  work  is  The  Principles  of  Scientific  Management,  New  York:  Harper, 
1919.  See  also  Cookc,  Morris  L.,  "Influence  of  Scientific  Management  Upon  Government," 
Bulletin  of  the  Taylor  Society,  1921,  Vol.  9,  pp.  31-38;  Pearson,  Norman  M.,  "Fayolism  As  the 
Necessary  Complement  of  Taylorism,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  p. 
68  ff. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  35 

arisen  to  modify  the  methods  of  citizen  research  agencies.18  One  was  sig- 
nified by  the  creation  at  Chicago  in  1933  of  the  Public  Administration 
Service.  PAS  emphasized  the  importance  of  work  planning  and  scheduling 
in  administrative  operations.  It  also  specialized  in  the  development  of  units 
of  work  measurement  and  systems  of  administrative  reporting  which  its  staff 
stood  ready  not  only  to  recommend  but  to  install.19  This  approach  was 
based  on  a  conviction  of  the  higher  value  of  helping  the  administrator  to 
meet  his  needs,  rather  than  redrawing  organization  charts  and  reshuffling 
functions. 

The  other  source  of  competition  with  traditional  administrative  research 
is  the  development  during  the  twenties  and  thirties  at  all  levels  of  govern- 
ment of  specialized  staff  facilities  as  official  agencies  of  management  research. 
The  work  of  continuous  study  of  governmental  organization  and  operations 
as  a  basis  for  the  annual  scrutiny  of  departmental  budget  estimates;  the 
supervision  of  the  methods  of  approving  and  recording  obligations  and 
expenditures;  the  application  of  the  personnel  classification  plan  to  the 
recruitment,  selection,  promotion  and  transfer  of  employees — these  and 
similar  central  staff  activities  are  in  sum  a  continuous  process  of  research 
into  the  programs  and  methods  of  the  various  agencies.  Perhaps  the  out- 
standing contribution  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative 
Management  was  the  way  in  which  it  highlighted  the  value  of  staff  and 
control  agencies  as  tools  of  coordination  for  the  chief  executive.  Its  report 
reviewed  the  federal  experience  of  twenty  years  with  the  Bureau  of  Effi- 
ciency (1913-33)  and  laid  the  foundation  for  the  program  of  the  Budget 
Bureau's  Division  of  Administrative  Management  after  1939. 

Consolidation  of  central  responsibility  for  general  efficiency  in  the  agency 
of  budgetary  coordination  symbolizes  another  aspect  of  strengthened  gov- 
ernmental management.  Staffs  engaged  in  recurrent  processes  of  agency 
coordination  are  stimulated  by  an  energetic  group  of  management-minded 
colleagues  who  are  freed  from  day-by-day  responsibilities  to  make  intensive 
analyses  of  specific  problems,  supplementing  the  knowledge  gained  in  or- 
dinary budgetary  relationships  with  the  operating  departments.  This 
catalytic  function  of  a  management  staff,  coordinated  with  the  units  of 
budgetary,  statistical,  and  other  government-wide  controls  in  the  Executive 
Office  of  the  President,  represents  the  latest  development  of  federal  ad- 

18  Cf.  the  discussion  presented   in   "Better  City  Government,"  Annals  of  the  American 
Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,   1938,  Vol.   199,  pp.   171-189;  Proceedings  of  the 
Governmental    Research    Association,    Governmental   Research   and   Citizen    Control   of   Gov- 
ernment, Detroit,  1940. 

19  Ridley,  Clarence  E.  and  Simon,  Herbert  A.,  Measuring  Municipal  Activities,  2d.  cd., 
Chicago:    International   City  Managers  Association,    1943;  National  Committee  on  Municipal 
Reporting,   Public   Reporting,   New    York:     Municipal    Administration   Service,    1931;    Public 
Administration   Service,   The   Work    Unit  in  Federal  Administration,  Chicago,    1937;   Stone, 
Donald   C.,   The  Management  of  Municipal  Public   Works,  Chicago:    Public  Administration 
Service,  1939. 


36  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

ministrative  planning.20  It  affords  the  President  the  benefit  of  a  general- 
staff  approach  in  the  exercise  of  his  administrative  responsibilities. 

The  decade  of  the  thirties  thus  witnessed  a  shift  of  the  center  of  gravity 
in  governmental  research  from  private  citizen-supported  agencies  outside 
the  government  to  central  staff  agencies  within  the  government  itself. 
At  the  same  time,  there  rose  a  trend  away  from  the  idea  of  central  agencies 
as  direct  controllers  of  line  officials  toward  the  concept  of  central  assistance 
in  line  operations  by  clarification  of  administrative  objectives,  stimulation 
of  work  planning  and  scheduling,  and  cooperation  with  departmental 
managers  in  establishing  units  of  measurement  and  standards  of  perform- 
ance. The  information  about  agency  activities  derived  from  these  processes 
makes  available  to  the  chief  executive  an  invaluable  flow  of  ideas  divorced 
as  nearly  as  may  be  from  vested  departmental  interests.  However,  thus 
far  the  potentialities  of  executive  staff  planning  as  a  focal  point  of  leader- 
ship and  direction  in  formulating  substantive  policy  have  not  yet  crystal- 
lized beyond  stimulation,  advice,  and  raising  of  issues.21 

Reaffirmation  of  the  Political  Context.  After  forty  years  of  research, 
development  of  tools  of  administrative  analysis  and  control,  and  evolution 
of  a  professional  spirit  among  students  and  practitioners  of  administration 
as  such,  it  .is  not  surprising  that  speculation  has  arisen  about  the  fitness  of 
persons  experienced  and  trained  in  the  administrative  arts  to  contribute  to 
the  formulation  of  policy.  This  is  one  of  the  great  unsettled  issues  of  ad- 
ministrative  theory.  General  discussions  about  the  "managerial  revolution" 
have  drawn  attention  to  it,  but  have  imputed  a  greater  assurance  and 
solidarity  among  the  elements  comprising  the  managerial  groups  than 
actually  exists.  The  issue  is  bound  up  with  other  complex  problems.  These 
include:  (1)  the  appropriate  code  of  behavior  in  the  area  intermediate 
between  the  setting  of  administrative  policy  under  law  and  legislative 
policy-making;  (2)  the  proper  balance  between  the  judgments  of  subject- 
matter  experts  and  line  operators  on  the  one  hand  and  those  of  manage- 
ment planners  and  staff  experts  on  the  other;  (3)  the  claims  of  the  lawyers 
in  the  entire  realm  of  law-making  and  rule-making;  and  (4)  the  nature  of 
"bureaucratic  ideology."  On  this  last  point,  some  feel  that  administrative 
agencies  are  responsible  for  achieving  desirable  social  purposes  and  may 

20  Cf.    Willoughby,  W.  F.,  Principles  of  Public  Administration,  ch.  5,  Washington:   Insti- 
tute of  Government  Research,   1929;  Jump,  W.  A.,  "Budgetary  and  Financial  Administration 
in  an  Operating  Department  of  the  Federal  Government,"  Proceedings  cit.  in  note  18,  p.  78  ff.\ 
Stone,  Donald  C.,  "Federal  Administrative  Management,  1932-42,"  Transactions  of  the  American 
Society  of  Mechanical  Engineers,  1943,  Vol.  65,  p.  242  ff.;  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  'The  Future 
Organizational   Pattern  of  the  Executive  Branch,"  American  Political  Science  Review,   1944, 
Vol.38,  p.  11791?. 

21  For  a  discussion  of  policy  planning  as  distinct  from  administrative  planning,  cf.  Key, 
V.  O.,  "Politics  and  Administration,"  in  White,  Leonard  D.,  cd.,  The  Future  of  Government 
in  the  United  States,  Chicago:   University  of  Chicago  Press,  1942.   The  wartime  development 
of  the  Office  of  Economic  Stabilization  and  the  Office  of  War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion 
is  significant  in  the  functional  differentiation  between  the  two  forms  of  planning. 


THE   STUDY  OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  37 

have  to  fight  for  them.  Others  think  administrative  agencies  should  con- 
fine themselves  to  getting  their  assignments  done  within  the  policies 
established  by  the  legislative  body. 

Discussion  over  the  past  fifteen  years  of  such  questions  as  those  of  ad- 
ministrative finality,  administrative  discretion,  and  administrative  respon- 
sibility22 reveals  a  shift  in  administrative  research.  Concern  with  technical 
expertness  and  specialized  experience  has  yielded  to  study  of  the  factors 
involved  in  the  management  of  an  organization  and  the  objectives  or  values 
toward  which  governmental  organizations  should  strive.  The  assumption 
of  thirty  years  ago  about  the  role  of  public  administration  in  a  democratic 
society  is  no  longer  controlling.  Then  the  whole  argument  rested  on  the 
thesis  that  democracy  and  efficiency  in  administration  were  not  incompatible. 
The  question  was  how  to  make  democratic  administration  efficient  and 
effective  in  the  face  of  arbitrary  political  interference  in  administrative 
matters.  Today  it  is  assumed  that  the  criteria  of  efficiency  in  democratic 
administration  are  broader  than  and  superior  to  technically  sound  procedure 
and  financial  economy  in  the  execution  of  established  policies. 

The  importance  of  technical  competence  and  professional  standards  is 
not  underestimated.  However,  the  tests  of  adequate  administration  are 
thought  to  go  beyond  the  accomplishment  of  statutory  purposes.  It  is 
argued  that  administrative  activities  should  be  studied  with  a  view  to  de- 
fining emerging  problems  and  developing  policy  recommendations  to  meet 
demands  for  new  services  or  types  of  regulation.  It  was  not  a  bureaucrat 
but  a  farsighted  and  successful  businessman  who  pointed  out  that  adminis- 
trative ability  of  the  highest  order  is  required  for  attainment  of  greater 
social  unity — the  unity  that  comes  from  general  understanding  and  satis- 
faction on  the  part  of  all  groups  with  respect  to  the  constructive  planning 
and  coordination  of  public  services  by  their  government.23 

3.    TRAINING  FOR  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

Educational  Aspects.  The  advancement  and  maturity  of  public  ad- 
ministration as  a  profession  may  be  appraised,  apart  from  its  assumptions 
and  its  techniques,  by  the  types  of  training  provided  and  the  standards  of 
admission  required  of  aspirants  for  entrance.  Of  course,  there  is  no 
single  vocational  group  of  administrators  in  the  public  service.  This 


22  See  Gaus  and  Others,  op.  cit.  in  note  1,  chs.  6  and  7;  Landis,  James  M.,  The  Adminis* 
trative  Process,  New  Haven:    Yale  University  Press,   1938;  Friedrich,  Carl  J.,  "Public  Policy 
and  the  Nature  of  Administrative  Responsibility,'*  in  Friedrich,  C.  J.  and  Mason,  Edward  S., 
eds.,   Public  Policy,   pp.   3-24,  Cambridge:    Harvard   University  Press,    1940;   Finer,  Herman, 
"Administrative    Responsibility    in    Democratic   Government,"    Public   Administration    Review, 
1940,  Vol.  1,  pp.  335-49. 

23  Dennison,  Henry  S.,  "The  Need  for  the  Development  of  Political  Science  Engineering," 
American   Political  Science  Review,    1932,  Vol.  26,  p.  241   ff.    See  aho  Merriam,  Charles  E., 
'The  New  Management,"  in  his  The  New  Democracy  and  the  New  Despotism,  New  York: 
McGraw-Hill,  1939. 


38  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

service  includes  every  profession  and  every  skill  within  the  range  of  func- 
tions and  activities  performed  for  the  community.  Yet  proper  training 
for  government  work  has  been  a  matter  of  deep  interest  among  the  organi- 
zations of  public  officials  and  the  political  science  departments  in  colleges 
and  universities  all  over  the  country.  In  the  course  of  the  last  twenty-five 
years  there  has  been  an  increasing  crystallization  of  ideas  and  methods  of 
approach. 

However  diverse  the  forms  of  government  action  may  be,  the  manage- 
ment of  public  business  is  recognized  as  a  field  of  career  activity  for  which 
it  is  possible  to  provide  training  and  incentives  to  attract  the  highest 
ability  in  the  population.  In  an  authoritative  survey,24  Professor  George  A. 
Graham  takes  the  position  that  training  for  public  administration  is  not  a 
special  professional  apprenticeship  but  part  of  the  broad  problem  of  edu- 
cational policy.  Its  ideal  is  continuous  growth  and  widening  experience 
for  the  able  individual  as  he  prepares  himself  to  meet  successive  tests  of 
competence  for  tasks  of  greater  responsibility.  To  attract  ability  and  talent 
into  the  public  service,  government,  recruitment  should  be  coordinated  with 
graduation  from  the  several  levels  of  school  and  college.  Public  personnel 
agencies  should  encourage  efforts  on  the  part  of  government  workers  to 
advance  themselves  by  providing  training  facilities  both  for  appropriate 
specialization  and  for  widening  their  intellectual  horizons. 

Such  a  policy  would  not  favor  the  establishment  of  a  separate  program 
in  educational  institutions  emphasizing  preparation  for  the  public  service 
exclusively.  It  would,  on  the  contrary,  foster  efforts  to  establish  a  university- 
wide  program  of  guidance,  information,  and  flexible  interdepartmental 
arrangements  for  selection  of  courses,  standards  of  examination,  and  re- 
quirements of  evidence  of  creative  ability.25  Similarly,  after  entrance  into 
the  public  service,  there  would  not  be  a  special  staff  college  for  prospective 
government  managers  only.  Rather,  there  would  be  a  process  of  sifting, 
competition  for  opportunities,  forward-looking  supervision,  and  promotion 
across  divisional  or  departmental  lines,  based  upon  a  service-wide  policy 
under  the  direction  of  the  central  personnel  agency. 

Public  administration  is  not  identified  by  a  distinctive  technique  of  its 
own,  a  single  type  of  activity,  or  a  unified  subject  matter  upon  which 
agreement  can  be  reached  for  purposes  of  establishing  a  special  curriculum. 
On  the  contrary,  at  the  undergraduate  level,  substantial  agreement  exists 
that  a  broad  liberal  education  is  the  best  prescription.  It  should  include  a 
realistic  awareness  of  the  operation  of  economic  institutions  and  the  role 
of  government  in  modern  society,  supplemented  if  possible  by  some  work 
in  statistics  or  accounting.  It  should  stress  the  ability  to  speak  and  write 

3* Graham,  George  A.,  Education  for  Public  Administration,  Chicago:  Public  Adminis- 
tration Service,  1941. 

25  Cf.  Lambie,  Morris  B.,  cd.,  Training  for  the  Public  Service,  Chicago:  Public  Adminis- 
tration Service,  1935. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  39 

the  English  language  effectively.  This  would  be  a  better  preparation  than 
training  for  a  specific  job.26  In  postgraduate  work,  all  types  of  pro- 
fessional schools  are  potential  sources  of  recruits  for  government  work. 
Professional  training  in  the  natural  sciences,  engineering,  education,  medi- 
cine, social  work,  law,  economics,  and  governmental  research,  culminating 
in  professional  degrees,  is  increasingly  accepted  as  experience  which  civil 
service  commissions  will  consider  as  qualification  for  intermediate  positions 
in  the  classified  service.  In  pre-entry  training  for  public  service,  therefore, 
we  find  little  disposition  to  provide  a  specific  occupational  preparation. 

Contrast  with  Great  Britain.  Since  the  University  of  Minnesota  Con- 
ference in  1931,  much  attention  has  been  devoted  to  the  question  of  whether 
the  elements  of  management  constitute  a  subject  matter  that  can  be  taught 
apart  from  application  to  technical  fields  of  administrative  activity  such  as 
public  health,  public  works,  public  welfare;  and,  if  so,  whether  it  would 
qualify  the  student  for  administrative  work.27  Actually,  no  program  of 
training  for  public  service  has  attempted  to  teach  the  knowledge  and  art  of 
management  in  a  vacuum.  Syracuse  University,  perhaps  the  outstanding 
example  of  a  special  program  of  graduate  training  aimed  at  government 
service,  uses  the  block  or  "end-on-end"  method  of  instruction  to  impart 
both  the  techniques  of  management  and  understanding  of  special  areas  of 
subject  matter.  Its  graduates  have  found  ready  markets  for  their  services, 
particularly  in  budget  and  personnel  agencies. 

Recruitment  for  the  civil  service  in  the  United  States  has  never  followed 
the  lines  recommended  by  the  Northcote-Trevelyan  and  Macaulay  reports 
for  Great  Britain  in  1853-54.28  These  reports  advocated  the  recruitment  of 
the  top  men  in  the  graduating  classes  of  the  British  universities,  regardless 
of  the  subject  of  specialization,  for  the  highest  administrative  positions  in 
the  civil  service,  coupled  with  a  suitable  period  of  post-entry  training  and 
qualification.  In  this  country,  at  least  up  to  1934,  the  policy  of  civil  service 
recruitment  has  been  based  upon  the  assumption  that  government  work 
can  be  classified  into  occupational  groupings  within  vertical  services.  After  the 
amount  of  training  and  experience  required  for  the  job  classification  within 
each  such  service  has  been  determined,  qualified  applicants  are  recruited 
by  competitive  examination  as  positions  become  vacant.  This  policy  places 
a  premium  upon  professional  or  vocational  experience.  A  good  deal  of 

20  Sec  White,  Introduction  (cit.  in  note  9),  pp.  356-360;  Sims,  Lewis  B.,  "The  Social 
Science  Analyst  Examinations,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1939,  Vol.  33,  pp.  441-450. 

27  Cf.   Meriam,  Lewis,  Public  Service  and  Special  Training.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1936;  Upson,  Lent  D.,  Ptactice  of  Municipal  Administration,  New  York:  Century,  1926; 
Walker,  Harvey,  Public  Administration  in  the  United  States,  pt.  Ill,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rine- 
hart,  1937. 

28  See  Eaton,   Dorman   B.,   Civil  Service  in   Great  ^Britain,  New  York:    National   Civil 
Service  Reform  League,    1881;  White,  Leonard  D.  and  Others,  Civil  Service  Abroad,  New 
York:    McGraw-Hill,   1935;  Stout,  Hiram  M.,  Public  Service  in  Great  Britain,  New  York: 
Harcourt  Brace,  1938;  Kingslcy,  Donald,  Representative  Bureaucracy.  Yellow  Springs:   Antioch 
Press,  1944. 


40  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

criticism  has  been  leveled  against  it  on  the  ground  that  in  the  absence  of 
clear  career  lines  able  young  men  and  women  of  general  competence,  lack- 
ing specific  experience,  are  likely  to  look  elsewhere  for  their  life  work. 

The  decade  from  1934  to  1944  was  notable  for  the  efforts  made  to  im- 
prove the  quality  of  intake  in  the  lower  grades  of  the  public  service.  In 
1934,  largely  at  the  instigation  of  Commissioner  Leonard  D.  White,  the 
United  States  Civil  Service  Commission  conducted  an  examination  for 
junior  civil  service  examiner,  for  which  post  academic  training  constituted 
the  principal  requirement.  In  1936,  a  broader  category  of  social  science 
analysts  was  established  as  a  register  from  which  appointments  might  be 
made  by  departments  seeking  general  ability  rather  than  specific  experience. 
From  January,  1935,  through  March,  1939,  more  than  5,000  such  junior 
professional  appointments  were  made  by  federal  agencies. L>t)  In  1934,  the 
National  Institute  of  Public  Affairs  was  established  in  Washington;  an- 
nually it  offered  about  fifty  men  and  women  just  out  of  college  the  oppor- 
tunity to  study  at  first  hand  the  operations  of  federal  agencies  in  the  capacity 
of  learners,  or  interns.  Programs  of  municipal  internship  also  received 
impetus  and  encouragement  at  such  institutions  as  Syracuse  University, 
Wayne  University,  and  the  University  of  Cincinnati.  Apprenticeship  pro- 
grams were  experimentally  developed  by  several  of  the  national  organiza- 
tions of  public  officials  associated  with  the  Public  Administration  Clearing 
House  at  Chicago,  the  Michigan  Municipal  League,  and  Los  Angeles 
County. 

Post-Entry  Training.  Most  of  the  present  activity  and  support  of  pre- 
entry  preparation  for  public  service  is  aimed  at  the  college  population. 
Post-entry  or  in-service  training  remains  the  main  opportunity  of  advance- 
ment for  the  lower-paid  ranks  in  public  employment,  particularly  in  the 
clerical  and  manual  occupations.  Universities,  where  located  in  proximity 
to  large  groups  of  government  workers,  such  as  Southern  California,  have 
established  courses  for  public  employees,  particularly  in  the  fields  of  budget- 
ing and  accounting,  police  and  fire  administration,  tax  assessment  and 
sanitary  inspection.  A  source  of  financial  aid  is  available  to  states  and 
municipalities  under  the  George-Deen  Act  of  1936  for  vocational  training 
in  public-service  occupations.30 

In  the  national  capital  the  outstanding  program  of  in-service  training 
is  that  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture's  Graduate  School,  whose  cur- 
riculum and  faculty  provide  some  of  the  best  technical  courses  in  public 
administration  in  the  country.  American  University  and  George  Washing- 
ton University,  also  at  the  seat  of  the  federal  government,  offer  evening 


^Report  of  President's  Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improvement,  77th  Cong.,  1st  Sess., 
House  Doc.  No.  118,  p.  25,  Washington,  1941.  Less  than  half  (2,421)  of  these  appointments 
were  made  from  other  lists  built  up  from  the  usual  kind  of  competitive  examination. 

30  See  United  States  Office  of  Education,  Digest  of  Annual  Reports  of  State  Boards  for 
Vocational  Education,  pp.  61-62,  Washington,  1942-1943. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  41 

courses  in  practically  all  the  social  sciences.  With  the  several  law  schools, 
they  have  trained  many  men  and  women  who  started  as  clerks  and  mes- 
sengers for  higher  administrative  and  professional  positions.  In  the  federal 
service,  post-entry  training  is  not  highly  formalized.31  It  consists,  for  the 
most  part,  in  encouraging  enterprising  individuals  to  seek  additional  educa- 
tion outside  their  jobs  rather  than  establishing  in-service  programs  directly 
related  to  the  official  machinery  for  promotion. 

Group  Structure  of  the  Public  Service.  Perhaps  the  main  reason  why 
post-entry  training  has  not  been  more  closely  coordinated  with  official  chan- 
nels of  advancement  lies  in  the  American  distaste  for  formal  division  of  the 
public  service  into  relatively  closed  classes  around  which  real  career  incen- 
tives might  develop.  The  Commission  of  Inquiry  on  Public  Service  Per- 
sonnel proposed  separate  careers  for  administrative,  professional,  clerical, 
skilled-trade,  and  unskilled  employees.  These  proposals  have  never  received 
the  serious  public  attention  they  deserve.32  In  spite  of  careful  explanations 
that  an  administrative  class  would  serve  as  a  vertical  ladder  leading  from 
junior  staff  positions  or  below  to  administrative  assistants  and  on  to  the 
top,  the  impression  continues  to  prevail  that  such  an  arrangement  would 
reserve  the  top  positions  under  the  political  secretaries  and  assistant  secre- 
taries for  a  special  group  who  would  be  favored  at  the  expense  of  able  per- 
sons in  the  clerical,  technical,  or  professional  services. 

Regardless  of  the  merits  of  this  objection,  it  is  clear  that  a  systematic 
solution  could  be  worked  out  if  law  and  personnel  policy  permitted  training 
for  admin:strative  work  as  distinguishable  from  professional,  technical,  or 
scientific  duties.  Until  such  differentiation  is  adopted  in  American  per- 
sonnel practice,  however,  top  administrative  positions  will  be  filled  both 
by  appointment  from  outside  the  service  and  by  promotion  from  the  ranks 
of  professional  and  technical  employees.  Under  these  conditions,  pre-entry 
programs  of  training  for  public  administration  will  have  to  rely  more  upon 
general  motives  of  public  service  and  increasing  job  opportunities  in  gov- 
ernment than  upon  the  specific  attractions  of  a  career  in  management. 

Higher  Career  Opportunities.  Even  without  legislative  sanction  of  an 
administrative  class,  much  could  be  done  by  a  central  personnel  agency  to 
maintain  such  an  ideal  as  a  long-range  objective.  Constructive  suggestions 
looking  forward  to  the  establishment  of  an  "administrative  corps"  were 
made  by  the  Reed  Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improvement  in  1941. 33 
These  included:  identification  of  positions  in  specified  grades  as  a  group; 

31  For  a  recent  development,  sec  Reining,  Henry,  Jr.,  "The  First  Federal  In-Service  Intern- 
ship Program,"  Personnel  Administration,  1944,  Vol.  7,  p.  8  ff. 

32  Better  Government  Personnel,  pp.  5-6,  37-47,  New  York:    McGraw-Hill,  1935. 
3377th  Cong.,    1st  Scss.,  House  Doc.  No.    118,  p.  3,   56-62,   86-97,  Washington,   1941. 

Sec  also  White,  Leonard  D.,  Government  Career  Service,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press, 
1935.  The  Council  of  Personnel  Administration  and  the  Advisorv  Committee  to  the  Civil  Service 
Commission  on  Administrative  Personnel  have  attempted  to  follow  through  on  the  Reed  Com- 
mittee's proposals  on  a  higher  administrative  service. 


42  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

maintenance  of  an  inventory  of  personnel  in  these  positions  for  use  in  making 
appointments  to  higher  administrative  posts;  reporting  of  vacancies  in 
higher  positions;  recommending  candidates  with  tested  qualifications  to 
appointing  officers;  and  follow-up  on  action.  -It  was  asserted  that  tapping 
and  training  personnel  for  positions  in  the  lowest  grade  of  the  administra- 
tive group  should  be  a  continuing  objective  of  agency  personnel  officers 
at  all  times,  while  a  liberal  policy  permitting  transfer  of  such  personnel 
between  agencies  would  widen  their  experience  and  develop  general 
administrative  skill.  The  major  obstacle  to  adoption  of  these  suggestions  is 
the  difficulty  of  finding  enough  departmental  personnel  officers  willing  and 
able  to  cooperate  on  an  informal  basis,  particularly  in  the  face  of  strong 
pressure  upon  each  to  place  his  own  agency's  needs  above  the  requirements 
of  the  service  as  a  whole. 

One  way  of  raising  the  question  of  whether  the  federal  service  needs 
an  administrative  corps  would  be  to  ask  if  such  a  pool  of  talent  could  have 
produced  adequate  competence  to  plan  and  direct  the  civilian  side  of  opera- 
tions during  World  War  II.  War  experience  is  not  wholly  conclusive  be- 
cause of  the  vast  expansion  of  government.  Yet  it  is  worth  noting  that,  with 
but  rather  few  exceptions,  the  higher  administrators  in  the  war  agencies 
came  from  the  other  branches  of  government  or  from  the  outside.  In 
civilian  recruitment,  the  Civil  Service  Commission  at  an  early  stage  sus- 
pended its  usual  procedures.  It  authorized  the  war  agencies  to  appoint  per- 
sonnel subject  only  to  investigation  and  certification  as  to  general  qualifica- 
tions. Moreover,  in  their  procurement  and  supply  operations,  the  War 
and  Navy  Departments  commissioned  thousands  of  civilians  to  perform 
administrative  tasks.  We  reached  everywhere  for  administrative  talent. 

In  establishing  its  wartime  organization  the  federal  government  implicitly 
admitted  that  peacetime  agencies  and  their  personnel  could  not  primarily  be 
relied  upon  to  plan  and  direct  the  civilian  phase  of  warfare.  While  a  fully 
developed  administrative  service  would  not  by  itself  have  made  unnecessary 
the  creation  of  emergency  agencies,  it  might  well  have  prevented  or  sub- 
stantially minimized  the  administrative  crises  and  continuous  improvisation 
that  characterized  the  first  two  years  after  Pearl  Harbor.  The  essential 
lesson  of  American  wartime  personnel  experience  was  that  we  were  short  of 
men  and  women  who  possessed  the  ability  to  envisage  the  problems  ahead 
and  formulate  decisions  in  advance  of  crisis  situations. 

Perhaps  the  most  compelling  peacetime  consideration  in  favor  of  a  higher 
administrative  career  is  the  continuous  loss  to  government  of  able  younger 
employees  who,  having  developed  their  talent  within  the  public  service,  leave 
for  more  responsible  and  more  challenging  work  in  private  enterprise. 

4.  THE  FRONTIERS  OF  RESEARCH 

Function  Versus  Structure.  The  accumulation  of  research  materials  and 
the  maturation  of  administrative  research  during  the  thirties  produced 


THE  STUDY  OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  43 

both  a  textbook  systematization  of  knowledge  and  considerable  philosophic 
inquiry  into  the  nature,  purpose,  and  scope  of  public  administration.  The 
textbooks  revealed  preoccupation  with  such  matters  as  the  symmetry  of 
administrative  structure  and  the  procedures  of  good  administrative  house- 
keeping. They  also  raised  the  question  of  whether  public  administration 
consisted  of  nothing  more  than  an  exposition  of  abstract  principles  of  organi- 
zation and  a  body  of  experience  aimed  at  training  budget  and  personnel 
officers.  Was  this  the  whole  meaning  of  public  service,  and  the  basis  for 
attracting  ability  into  government  employment? 

The  experience  of  management  research  in  private  industry  ha'd  revealed 
the  error  of  stating  principles  of  organization  as  ends,  or  even  as  major 
purposes.  Industrial  management  now  starts  from  an  assumption  about  the 
basic  purpose  of  the  organization  as  a  whole.  It  encourages  research  to 
develop  the  best  ways  and  means  of  achieving  that  purpose.  Paralleling  this 
approach,  government  research  turned  to  the  public  purpose  sought  to  be 
achieved.  In  it  was  seen  the  rationale  for  organization,  the  planning  of 
operations,  the  creation  of  staff  units  to  facilitate  operations,  and  the  estab- 
lishment of  goals  and  standards  as  well  as  methods  of  measuring  results 
in  relation  to  the  standards  selected. 

This  analysis  of  management  shifts  the  emphasis  from  structure  to 
function.  It  also  defines  the  key  problem  as  the  establishment  of  effective 
working  relations  between  the  component  parts  of  the  organization."34  The 
emphasis  upon  planning  and  coordination  as  essential  elements  of  manage- 
ment helped  to  reorient  the  thinking  of  public  administration  toward  the 
functions  of  top  direction.  Thus  the  budgeting  and  personnel  functions  pre- 
sented themselves  as  techniques  of  work  planning  and  coordination,  and 
as  training  areas  for  potential  managerial  talent,  rather  than  as  central 
concerns  of  the  public  administrator. 

Man  in  Organization.  Discussion  of  the  elements  of  organization,  how- 
ever realistic,  aims  at  some  invariant  ideas  on  basic  points  for  thinking, 
and  hence  tends  to  depersonalize  the  problems  of  management.  Arthur  W, 
Macmahon  and  John  D.  Millett  developed  a  more  productive  approach 
through  an  analysis  of  the  role  of  personalities  in  the  major  departments  in 
the  federal  government.3'1  Their  idea  was  that  a  description  of  background, 
training,  and  career  experience  of  administrators  at  the  levels  of  bureau  chief 
and  assistant  secretary  should  adduce  useful  evidence  of  managerial  traits. 
The  result  was  an  extremely  valuable  interpretation  of  varying  types  of 
administrative  supervision  and  departmental  coordination  arising  from  the 
diversity  of  personal  development  and  the  adjustments  made  by  key  officers. 

34  Cf.    Person,    H.    S.,    cd.,    Scientific    Management   in    American    Industry,    New    York: 
Harper,   1929;  Mooncy,  James  D.  and  Rcilcy,  Alan  C,  Onward  Industry,  New  York:  Harper, 
1931,   and    The   Principles   of    Organization,   New   York:    Harper,    1939;   Dennison,   Henry, 
Organisation  Engineering,  New  York:  Dutton,  1931. 

35  Macmahon,   A.   W.  and   Millett,   J.  D.    Federal  Administrators,  New  York:    Columbia 
University  Press,   1939. 


44  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

The  new  approach  illustrated  the  impact  of  personality  upon  organization. 
It  extracted  the  common  elements  of  managerial  experience  gained  in 
attempting  to  create  departmental  unity  out  of  separate  bureau  operations. 

Biographical  research  was  also  utilized  by  Gaus  and  Wolcott  in  their 
monumental  study  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture.36 
Instead  of  drawing  wider  inferences  from  personal  data,  however,  Gaus 
and  Wolcott  used  such  material  as  one  among  several  colors  with  which  they 
painted  the  panorama  of  administrative  evolution  through  seventy  years  of 
political  response  to  powerful  economic  and  technological  pressures.  Their 
study  opened  broad  vistas  of  research  opportunities  in  administrative  history, 
focused  on  the  positive  role  of  a  public  agency  in  bringing  professional  and 
scientific  tools  to  bear  upon  the  economic  problems  of  a  large  segment  of 
the  population.  It  offered  chapter-and-verse  illustrations  of  the  way  a  public 
agency  formulates  broader  programs  and  policy,  leading  onward  toward 
constructive  public  service  through  the  educational  character  of  its  own 
experience.  The  authors  did  not  close  their  eyes  to  the  barriers  interposed 
by  strong  influences  in  favor  of  retaining  the  earlier  concepts  of  protective, 
group-centered  regulation.  The  literature  contains  no  finer  treatment  of 
public  administration  as  the  crucible  of  collective  experience  for  clarifying 
legislative  goals  and  for  developing  the  techniques  of  translating  objectives 
into  administrative  instruments  for  constructive  action. 

Theory  of  Relationships.  The  lifting  of  the  sights  of  administrative 
research  to  focus  upon  the  social  and  economic  environment  has  been 
largely  due  to  the  penetrating  writings  of  Mary  Parker  Follett  and  the  more 
systematic  work  at  the  Harvard  Business  School  under  the  leadership  of 
Elton  D.  Mayo.  Miss  Follett's  earlier  work  in  political  and  social  theory  had 
led  her  to  a  keen  appreciation  of  the  influence  of  organization  in  modern 
society.  At  the  same  time  she  had  reacted  strongly  against  the  ideologies 
of  group  and  class  conflict  which  constituted  both  factual  explanation  and 
political  hope  for  many  intellectuals  who  were  aware  of  antisocial  policies 
and  controls  over  modern  large-scale  production.  During  the  last  fifteen 
years  before  her  death  in  1933  she  became  interested  in  business  management 
and  organization  as  a  field  for  application  of  the  principles  of  unity  and 
organized  cooperation  that  she  had  developed  in  her  political  studies. 

In  this  new  field  of  interest  she  was  impressed  much  more  with  the 
conditions  tending  toward  cooperation  in  the  behavior  of  men  working  in 
groups  than  with  assumptions  about  inevitable  conflicts  of  interest.  In  a 
series  of  provocative  papers  and  lectures  she  showed  how  management,  by 
acting  on  the  premise  of  unity  in  organized  effort  instead  of  merely  paying 
lip  service  to  it,  could  gain  tremendous  strength  in  mobilizing  individual 

36  Gaus,  John  M.  and  Wolcott,  Leon  OM  Public  Administration  and  the  United  States 
Department  of  Agriculture,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1940. 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  45 

energies  for  a  common  purpose.87  Pervading  all  her  thinking  was  the  idea 
that  individuals  at  each  level  of  authority  in  an  organization  can  be  condi- 
tioned to  think  in  terms  of  unity.  However,  management  would  have  to 
make  the  effort  to  enable  them  to  sense  and  understand  their  contribution  to 
the  common  enterprise.  It  was  Mary  Follett's  abiding  faith  that  the  factors 
tending  toward  disunity  and  internal  conflict  can  be  faced  frankly;  that  to 
this  end  enlightened  management  will  open  up  channels  for  collective 
consideration  of  the  conditions  in  which  frictions  arise;  and  that  such  fric- 
tions stem  for  the  most  part  from  the  frustrations  and  disappointments  of  in- 
dividuals working  under  conditions  out  of  which  they  derive  no  sense  of 
personal  creativeness  or  contribution. 

The  research  of  the  Harvard  Business  School  into  the  springs  of  human 
motivation  in  business  organizations  has  given  us  the  benefit  of  a  scientific 
documentation  of  Miss  Follett's  insights.38  These  studies  applied  to  indus- 
trial research  both  anthropological  findings  and  sociological  concepts,  and 
added  much  sophistication  as  to  the  meaning  of  scientific  methods  of  inves- 
tigating social  relations.  The  record  of  the  Harvard  team's  association  with 
the  Western  Electric  experiments  in  personnel  relations  constitutes  perhaps 
the  high-water  mark  of  intensive  research  into  group  behavior  under  con- 
trolled conditions.  It  is  impossible  to  summarize  this  work  adequately,  but  a 
few  outstanding  findings  may  be  mentioned: 

First,  there  is  in  each  organization  a  system  of  informal  personal  rela- 
tionships which  condition  work  habits  and  attitudes  more  effectively 
than  the  official  hierarchy  of  authority.  The  student  must  develop  tech- 
niques of  observation  and  interview  to  enable  him  to  grasp  the  essential 
quality  of  the  organization  under  attention.  A  measure  of  his  own 
effectiveness  is  the  degree  to  which  he  is  accepted  within  the  system  and 
is  able  to  enlist  the  collaboration  of  those  whose  organizational  behavior 
he  is  studying. 

Second,  large  organizations  consist  of  many  working  groups,  each 
small  enough  to  effect  cohesion.  Morale  centers  around  such  groups, 
where  direct  personal  relationships  function  in  relation  to  a  set  of  non- 
logical  or  emotional  incentives  and  standards.  These  group  standards 
must  be  integrated  with  the  purpose  of  the  organization  as  a  whole 
and  not  permitted  to  develop  intergroup  conflicts.  Effective  management 
must  not  only  recognize  and  give  status  to  each  rank  in  its  own  social 
structure,  but  also  be  sure  to  establish  channels  of  communication  be- 
tween each  group  and  the  center  of  direction  in  the  organization. 

Third,  the  function  of  attaining  a  sense  of  interrelatedness  between 
the  working  groups  composing  the  organization  as  a  whole  is  a  full-time 

37  Her  collected  papers  are  reprinted  in  Metcalf,  H.  C.  and  Urwick,  L.,  eds.,  Dynamic 
Administration,  New  York:  Harper,  1941. 

S8  Cf.  Mavo,  Elton  D.,  The  Human  Problems  of  an  Industrial  Civilization,  New  York. 
Macmillan,  1933;  Whitehead,  T.  N.,  Leadership  in  a  Free  Society,  Cambridge:  Harvard  Uni- 
versity Press,  1936;  Roethlisbcrger,  Fritz,  J.  and  Dickson,  W.  J.,  Management  and  the  Worker, 
Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1943,  and  Roethlisberger,  Management  and  Morale, 
Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1941. 


46  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

job  which  top  management  cannot  leave  to  chance  or  to  the  part-time 
attention  of  supervisory  personnel.  Explicit  attention  must  be  given 
to  locating  and  reporting  human  dissatisfactions  at  the  working  levels, 
maintaining  harmony  among  the  groups  in  the  organization,  and  study- 
ing methods  of  introducing  changes  in  technical  processes  or  formal 
modifications  in  the  structure  itself. 

Progressive  Management.  The  importance  of  the  personnel  function 
in  organization  can  hardly  be  overstressed,  but  its  relation  to  the  central 
task  of  top  management  remains  to  be  stated.  In  response  to  the  Harvard 
group,  an  outstanding  business  executive,  Chester  I.  Barnard,  developed 
perhaps  the  most  systematic  analysis  of  the  executive  function  since  Henri 
Fayol.  Barnard  defined  organization  as  an  "impersonal  system  of  coordi- 
nated human  efforts."  He  identified  the  executive's  job  as:  (1)  providing 
the  system  of  communication;  (2)  securing  essential  services  from  indi- 
viduals; and  (3)  establishing  the  purposes  and  objectives  of  organiza- 
tion.39 In  his  formulation,  technical  efficiency  and  morale  are  not  the  pri- 
mary ends  of  organized  effort.  They  are  limiting  factors  bearing  upon  the 
permanence  or  duration  of  an  organization,  whose  existence  through  time 
depends  upon  its  effectiveness  in  attaining  both  the  concrete  ends  of  con- 
certed activity  and  essential  human  satisfactions.  Every  one  of  the  elements 
of  management  depends  upon  personnel.  While  the  selection  of  top  per- 
sonnel cannot  be  delegated,  the  task  of  functional  coordination  of  those  at 
the  lower  levels  must  be  related  to  the  purposes  of  the  organization  rathef 
than  to  the  managerial  function. 

All  of  these  propositions  show  how  far  modern  personnel  research  has 
gone  beyond  the  concept  of  management  as  the  application  of  fixed  rules 
of  organization  and  the  installation  of  technical  procedures  of  selection, 
training,  and  placement.  Public  administration  has  been  especially  receptive 
to  these  ideas.  The  growing  rapprochement  among  students  of  administra- 
tion in  public  and  private  enterprise  is  demonstrated  by  various  develop- 
ments. Two  illustrations  are  the  widespread  recognition  of  the  work  of 
Lyndall  Urwick40  and  the  collection  of  writings  in  both  fields  for  the 
staff  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management.41  The 
emphasis  on  matters  of  structure  among  private  management  consultants 
reflects  their  greater  confidence  in  the  validity  of  organizational  theory. 
Government  administrators  and  their  planning  staffs  are  more  acutely 
conscious  of  the  impact  of  political  influences  upon  public  organizations  and 
have  come  to  accept  these  pressures  as  a  normal  aspect  of  their  work. 

The  most  noteworthy  American  experiment  in  modern  managerial  free- 
dom to  accomplish  broad  objectives  of  public  policy — the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority — has  been  analyzed  in  a  brilliant  piece  of  administrative  reporting 

39  Barnard,  Chester  I.,  The  Functions  of  the  Executive,  csp.  chs.  7  and   15,  Cambridge: 
Harvard  University  Press,  1938. 

40  Urwick,  L.,  The  Elements  of  Administration,  New  York:  Harper,  1943. 

41  Gulick  and  Urwick,  op.  cit.  in  note  1 . 


THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  47 

by  its  chairman,  David  E.  Lilicnthal.42  The  author,  convinced  that  democ- 
racy can  plan  and  determine  the  course  of  its  political  evolution,  demon- 
strates the  results  that  public  management  can  achieve  in  the  utilization 
and  development  of  natural  resources.  Lilienthal  feels  deeply  that  TVA 
exemplifies  sound  democratic  administration — decentralized  operations, 
voluntary  citizen  cooperation  and  local  community  participation  with  gov- 
ernment officials  in  achieving  the  purpose  of  the  organization,  fixing  of 
responsibility  for  both  planning  and  execution  of  administrative  policy  upon 
a  single  agency,  a  personnel  policy  based  strictly  upon  merit  but  allowing 
for  constructive  flexibility,  and  an  enforcement  policy  of  education  and 
persuasion  that  relies  for  coercive  sanction  only  upon  the  power  of  eminent 
domain  in  the  public  interest. 

The  essence  of  democratic  administration,  Lilienthal  says,  is  doing  things 
with  people,  not  to  them,  and  placing  the  responsible  administrators  close 
to  the  people  where  they  must  share  the  people's  problems.  Method,  he 
asserts,  is  all-important;  "it  is  as  inseparable  from  purpose  and  ends  as  our 
flesh  is  from  our  blood."  Give  to  management  powers  of  affirming  and 
initiating  what  shall  be  done;  fix  upon  it  responsibility  for  results;  see  that 
the  experts  take  action  with  people  instead  of  simply  applying  legal  coercion 
— if  we  do  so,  we  may  be  sure  that  management  will  work  as  well  for  the 
public  interest  as  for  any  incentive  of  private  profit.  The  TVA  demonstra- 
tion is  a  revelation  of  the  enormous  potential  of  moral  power  available  to 
a  democratic  people  if  they  possess  the  courage  to  exploit  their  natural 
resources  for  the  common  benefit;  if  they  exercise  the  self-restraint  to  fix 
upon  the  administration  the  responsibility  and  freedom  to  decide  how  this 
should  best  be  done;  and  if  they  find  institutional  ways  of  holding  the 
managers  to  account  for  final  results. 

Horizons  of  Administrative  Research.  Research  in  public  administra- 
tion thus  has  pushed  steadily  backward  the  barriers  of  technical  separatism 
and  lack  of  communication  between  the  various  specialists  in  the  adminis- 
trative arts.  Scientific  methods  have  been  applied  to  the  study  of  the  human 
factor  in  organization.  The  inner  secrets  of  the  priesthood  of  management 
have  been  proved  to  be  susceptible  of  analysis.  Great  strides  have  been  made 
in  clarifying  the  relationship  of  budgetary  and  personnel  Coordination  to 
general  management. 

Above  all,  research  in  public  management  has  struggled  free  from  the 
notions  of  public  business  as  routine,  as  primarily  negative  and  restrictive 
upon  personal  or  private  initiative,  and  as  an  unnatural  but  necessary  evil. 
Study  of  the  modes  of  policy  formation  and  the  relationships  in  organiza- 
tion has  brought  about  an  understanding  of  the  psychological  processes 
of  personal  identification  with  the  individuality  and  achievements  of  the 
organization  as  a  whole.  Thus  public  administration  has  advanced  to  a 

*~TVA:    Democracy  on  the  March,  esp.  pp.  159-161,  199-202,  New  York:  Harper, 


48  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

realization  of  the  strong  sense  of  individual  release  and  satisfaction  in 
cooperating  with  others. 

Because  of  the  great  desirability  of  arriving  at  common  agreement  on 
public  needs  and  public  objectives,  increasing  research  in  the  borderline 
problems  lying  between  political  theory  and  public  administration  seems 
inevitable.4'1  Can  greater  consensus  be  reached  upon  the  creative  and  forma- 
tive roles  of  administrators  in  advising  on  the  best  means  of  defining  particu- 
lar objectives  and  establishing  the  administrative  machinery  for  achieving 
them?  How  should  administrative  agencies  attempt  to  integrate  their  activi- 
ties with  private  group  demands  and  drives  for  power?  How  can  political 
leadership  be  brought  to  utilize  properly  the  concepts  and  techniques  of 
administrative  planning  in  the  formulation  of  public  policies  and  programs? 
Can  new  forms  of  administrative  accountability  to  legislatures  and  to  the 
public  be  devised  which  will  increase  mutual  respect  and  lessen  suspicion 
and  distrust?  Can  the  educational  system  be  used  with  greater  effective- 
ness to  arouse  both  a  sympathetic  appreciation  of  the  problems  of  public 
management  and  a  desire  to  enter  the  public  service  in  the  minds  of  promis- 
ing individuals  representing  all  sections  of  the  population? 

These  are  problems  of  the  highest  order.  They  demand  unflagging  inter- 
est and  research.  For  satisfactory  progress,  we  need  to  establish  much  better 
contacts  with  foreign  administrative  experience.  Comparative  study,  of 
which  thus  far  we  have  had  too  little,  is  of  obvious  value. 

5.  ADMINISTRATION — ART  OR  SCIENCE? 

Aims  of  Scientific  Approach.  The  term  "science"  is  an  honorific  word. 
Considerable  effort  has  been  made  to  justify  its  use  in  identifying  the 
knowledge  and  skills  that  are  applied  in  administrative  practice.  A  science 
of  administration  in  the  sense  of  a  body  of  formal  statements  describing 
invariant  relationships  between  measurable  objects,  units,  or  elements  does 
not  seem  very  useful  to  most  students  and  practitioners.  Unquestionably, 
administrative  research  has  produced  a  sizable  body  of  definite  precepts  and 
hypotheses  that  are  applicable  to  concrete  situations.44  But  what  adminis- 
trators visualize  as  particularly  valuable  goes  beyond  that.  They  are  inter- 
ested in  the  techniques  of  systematizing  the  process  of  securing  and  sifting 
relevant  information  so  that  the  factors  involved  in  arriving  at  a  policy 
decision  can  be  stated  and  the  consequences  of  alternatives  can  be  analyzed 
and  balanced. 

The  objective  of  public  or  private  management  is  to  create  conditions 
under  which  a  determination  of  appropriate  action  can  be  made  in  terms 
of  a  plan  and  an  understanding  of  how  that  particular  decision  will  fit  into 

43  See   Merriam,   Charles   E.,    "Public   Administration   and   Political   Theory,"   Journal  o) 
Social  Philosophy,  1940,  Vol.  5.  p.  293  #.;  Political  Power,  pp.  285-296,  New  York:  McGraw- 
Hill,  1934. 

44  C/.  Beard,  op.  cit.  in  note  16,  pp.  163-J70;  Urwick,  op.  cit.  in  note  40,  pp.  17-19. 


THE  STUDY  OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  49 

the  plan.  From  this  angle,  administrative  research  does  not  seek  its  goal  in 
the  formulation  of  mechanical  rules  or  equations,  into  which  human  be- 
havior must  be  molded.  Rather,  it  looks  toward  the  systematic  ordering  of 
functions  and  human  relationships  so  that  organizational  decisions  can  and 
will  be  based  upon  the  certainty  that  each  step  taken  will  actually  serve  the 
purpose  of  the  organization  as  a  whole. 

Concerns  of  the  Technicians.  Naturally,  there  are  levels  of  routine  and 
technical  proficiency  on  which  greater  degrees  of  uniform  mechanical  opera- 
tion are  possible  and  desirable  than  at  others.  Research  should  continually 
seek  to  simplify  and  standardize  work  methods,  ranging  from  the  relatively 
simple  operation  of  sorting  incoming  mail  for  distribution  to  the  complex 
process  of  formulating  a  work  plan  for  an  entire  organization  in  the  annual 
budget.  However,, the  establishment  of  standardized  processes  and  mechani- 
cal efficiency  docs  not  penetrate  to  the  central  function  of  management. 
Absorption  into  this  more  limited  aspect  of  the  science  of  administration 
differentiates  the  operational  expert  and  technician  from  the  manager- 
administrator. 

Techniques  of  budgeting,  accounting,  personnel  management,  purchase, 
storage  and  handling  of  materials,  and  reporting  operations  are  indispensable 
tools  whereby  the  facts  involved  in  recurring  problem-situations  are  brought 
into  focus  for  the  administrator.  Yet  they  are  significant  to  him  only  as 
they  raise  issues  requiring  his  determination,  or  call  for  changes  in  the 
policy  of  the  organization.  Administrative  progress,  in  this  sense,  consists 
in  the  reduction  of  problems  to  routines  which  can  be  disposed  of  satis- 
factorily at  the  lower  levels. 

Science  and  Social  Dynamics.  Focusing  upon  the  problem  areas  of  social 
organization,  the  question  becomes  a  different  one.  How  far  is  it  a  matter  of 
science  to  exercise  judgment  in  selection  among  alternatives  of  policy,  in 
the  determination  of  specific  action  in  pursuit  of  the  purpose  of  the  organi- 
zation, or  in  the  interpretation  of  the  requirements  of  the  public  interest 
in  particular  cases?  If  this  question  were  to  be  answered  in  scientific  terms, 
the  answer  would  have  to  be  stated,  as  in  all  matters  of  social  relations,  in 
categories  upon  which  general  agreement  could  be  obtained.  We  have 
not  yet  reached  complete  agreement  on  the  purpores  and  powers  of  public 
officials,  or  on  a  formula  for  human  behavior  whereby  conflicts  of  interest 
and  will  can  be  predicted  and  determined  in  advance.  In  the  philosophy  and 
practice  of  democracy,  however,  it  has  been  learned  that  men  can  agree 
upon  constitutional  procedures  through  wh'ch  personal  and  intergroup 
conflicts  can  be  resolved  in  terms  of  general  policy,  basic  objectives,  and 
social  priorities. 

Evaluated  Experimentation.  Through  the  joint  action  of  public  officials, 
public  policy  can  be  tested,  tried  out,  and  changed  as  the  result  of  administra- 
tive experience  and  alert  leadership.  The  science  of  administration  in  a  de- 
mocracy will  never  be  simply  a  matter  of  definition;  it  will  always  be  a  mat- 


50  THE  STUDY  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

ter  of  living  and  striving.  Its  content  will  be  reflected  in  the  methods  by 
which  administrative  experience  is  applied  to  the  formulation  of  changing 
ideas  of  public  goals.  It  will  gain  more  specific  meaning  in  continuous  re- 
search into  the  problems  of  communication,  incentive,  and  morale  within 
both  public  and  private  organizations.  It  will  grow  through  the  insight  and 
ability  of  administrators  as  they  devise  ways  of  adjusting  their  programs  to 
the  conflicting  demands  and  ideals  of  their  consumer  publics  and  their 
political  overseers. 

Alliance  of  Theory  and  Practice.  This  view  of  a  democratic  science  of 
administration  assumes  a  unity  of  theory  and  practice,  and  at  the  same  time 
envisages  a  general — but  not  closed — functional  differentiation  between  its 
students  and  its  practitioners.  That  is  to  say,  administrative  research  must  be 
oriented  toward  actual  behavior  and  the  working  problems  of  administrators; 
continuous  efforts  must  be  made  to  encourage  such  research  and  to  bring  its 
results  to  the  attention  of  busy  administrators.*  The  suggestion  of  a  National 
Research  Library  for  this  purpose  has  been  made  on  several  occasions  by 
Professor  Charles  A.  Beard.  Furthermore,  administrative  research  must  not 
be  turned  into  the  handmaiden  of  officialdom  to  justify  the  preferences  of 
policy-makers  at  any  given  moment. 

The  profession  of  administration  should  include  both  the  research  worker 
and  the  executive.  They  should  collaborate  in  selecting  problems  for  study 
and  making  data  and  experience  available.  In  the  formulation  and  interpre- 
tation of  findings,  however,  there  will  always  be  room  for  initiative  and 
responsibility  outside  the  official  sphere.  It  is  to  be  hoped  that  students  of 
administration  in  universities,  business  organizations,  privately  supported 
research  institutions  and  public  agencies  will  all  seek  to  break  down  the 
invisible  barriers  of  distance,  suspicion,  and  difference  in  technique  and 
objective.  Through  professional  association  and  the  written  and  printed 
word,  it  should  be  possible  to  broaden  the  channels  of  communication  and 
understanding  between  public  and  private  organizations  for  mutually  helpful 
analysis  of  administrative  problems. 


CHAPTER 

3 

Bureaucracy— Fact  and  Fiction 

1.   SEMANTICS  AND  REALITIES 

The  tyranny  of  words  is  nowhere  better  exhibited  than  in  the  use  of  the 
word  "bureaucracy."  Governments  do  their  work  as  much  through  admin- 
istration as  through  politics.  It  might  therefore  be  supposed  that  in  a  dem- 
ocracy where  administrators  are  subject  to  direction  by  politicians  and  where 
politicians  derive  their  power  from  the  people,  popular  allusions  to  those 
who  manage  the  public  business  would  have  pleasing  connotations.  Perhaps 
that  is  the  way  it  ought  to  be.  For  the  present,  however,  the  opposite  is 
true,  and  will  be  for  some  time  to  come. 

The  Language  of  Contempt.  One  of  the  most  common  collective  desig- 
nations for  those  who  man  the  services  of  government  is  "bureaucracy." 
The  name  is  one  of  derision  and  contempt,  harsher,  to  be  sure,  in  some 
contexts  than  in  others  but  even  at  its  mildest  a  word  inviting  one  to  sneer 
or  scorn.1  The  prevalence  of  this  designation  may  be  regrettable;  yet  it  is  a 
fact,  and  as  such  something  not  simply  to  be  decried  but  to  be  acknowledged 
and  understood.  There  are  several  different  explanations  for  it.  Each 
warrants  brief  examination. 

As  is  evident  in  a  thousand  ways,  the  human  animal  is  fearfully  and 
wonderfully  made.  Man  knows  he  needs  the  discipline  of  authority.  Wher- 
ever he  has  come  far  enough  in  his  evolution  to  enter  the  political  stage  of 
development,  he  has  taken  steps  to  establish  such  authority.  But  even  as  he 
maintains  it,  he  still  resents  it  and  chafes  under  it.  Rationally  he  realizes 
that  freedom  is  unworkable  without  responsibility.  Emotionally  his  desire 
is  for  liberty  without  restraint.  In  this  sense  "cussin'  the  bureaucrats"  con- 
stitutes one  expression  of  human  nature,  destined  to  continue  as  long  as 
man  remains  on  the  earth. 

Habit  and  memory  furnish  another  explanation.    In  America,  popular 


1This  discussion  draws  on  Morstcin  Marx,  Fritz,  "Bureaucracy,"  in  Peel,  Roy  V.  and 
Roucek,  Joseph  S.,  cds.,  Introduction  to  Politics,  p.  410  //.,  New  York:  Crowcll,  1941.  Cf.  also 
Finer,  Herman,  "Critics  of  'Bureaucracy',"  Political  Science  Quarterly,  1945,  Vol.  60,  p.  100  ff. 

51 


52  BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION 

government,  as  most  people  think  of  it  today,  was  born  hardly  a  hundred 
years  ago.  Only  in  Britain  has  it  existed  for  anything  like  as  long  a  period. 
Elsewhere  in  what  are  now  free  countries — with  the  notable  exception  of 
Switzerland,  the  Scandinavian  nations,  the  Low  Countries  and  the  British 
Dominions — monarchy  and  aristocracy  continued  to  rule  not  only  in  form 
but  in  fact  until  the  late  nineteenth  and — in  some  cases — the  early  twentieth 
century.  Both  in  America,  therefore,  and  in  those  lands  across  the  sea 
whence  so  many  of  our  forbears  came,  government  of  the  people,  by  the 
people,  and  for  the  people  triumphed  only  after  centuries  of  autocratic  or 
aristocratic  rule  during  which  administration  was  frequently  overbearing 
if  not  inconsiderate  and  cruel.  Consequently,  it  was  in  some  measure  out 
of  their  own  mean  experience  that  the  common  people  came  to  damn  their 
public  "servants."  The  evil  being  long-continuing  and  the  people  remem- 
bering it  full  well  both  as  groups  and  as  individuals,  the  habit  has  persisted. 

Officiousness  and  Frailty.  Officiousness  is  a  third  factor  accounting  for 
the  unflattering  character  of  many  of  the  popular  references  to  the  adminis- 
trative profession.  Civil  servants  are  ordinary  mortals;  they  have  the  defects 
and  weaknesses  typical  of  human  nature.  Each  man  loves,  as  Shakespeare 
said,  "his  own  brief  moment  of  authority."  However,  some  seem  unable  to 
avoid  showing  their  glee,  and  of  these  the  public  service  probably  has  a 
normal  ratio.  It  is  so  in  all  countries}  Every  government  has  a  proportion 
of  otherwise  satisfactory  employees  who  do  their  work  in  a  fashion  that 
rubs  the  public  the  wrong  way. (This  "insolence  of  office"  naturally  comes 
in  for  greater  criticism  in  democratic  lands  like  America,  Britain,  France 
and  the  Scandinavian  countries.)  Yet  even  the  Germans  found  ways  of 
scoffing  at  Brownshirt  "bureaucrats"  while  Hitler  was  in  power.  Nor  have 
the  people  of  the  Soviet  Union  hesitated  to  lampoon  their  own  overreaching 
"functionaries."  The  combat  troops  of  all  armies  illustrate  in  their  scorn 
for  martinets  and  for  big-talking  paper-soldiers  berthed  at  headquarters 
the  military  equivalent  of  these  civilian  attitudes. 

'Further  probing  leads  to  a  more  serious  fact.  Occasionally  bureaucrats 
do  abuse  their  position  and  authority.  By  and  large,  the  governmental 
processes  of  modern  democracy  constitute  adequate  protection  against  official 
jpiscoaduct.  However,  these  procedures  are  not  always  fully  used  nor  are 
they  always  faithfully  observed.  Here  and  there  a  public  servant  attempts 
to  make  his  public  office  yield  a  private  gain  or  buckles  under  pressure  and 
uses  his  power  to  confer  illicit  advantage  on  some  special  group.  Il  should 
be  added  that  this  happens  more  often  among  bureaucrats  in  elective  than 
in  appointive  posts.  Although  the  guilty  are  not  always  caught  and  forced 
to  make  amends,  the  gross  volume  of  such  abuse  has  long  been  on  the 
decline. 

Administrative  Self -Promotion.  More  common  and  harder  to  cope  with 
is  a  wholly  different  kind  of  fault  which  often  arises  from  excess  of  zeal  in 
the  promotion  of  what  is  honestly  believed  to  be  the  public  interest.  That 


BUREAUCRACY  —  FACT  AND  FICTION  53 

is  the  inclination  of  some  public  administrators  to  take  too  expansive  a  view 
of  their  functions.  In_  order  tojacrnmplLsh  a  public  good  that  might  other- 
wise be  deferred  nr  Insr^  they  ypay  push  the  range  of  their  discretion  beyond 
the  limits  Amended  by  thg  legislature.  It  was  a  mistake,  Woodrow  Wilson 
argued,  to  relegate  administration  to  the  category  of  things  "which  clerks 
could  arrange  after  doctors  had  agreed  upon  principles."  But  it  is  equally  a 
mistake  —  and  in  a  democracy  a  dangerous  one  —  to  conceive  of  administra- 
tion ao  the  heroic  center  of  government.  Such  a  conception  might  encourage 
the  view  that  an  independent  executive,  beyond  carrying  out  the  policies 
formulated  by  the  legislature,  is  free  to  compensate,  ^through  administrative 
orders,  for  legislative  errors  of  omission  or  commission! 

Administration  has  been  called  the  core_of  modern-  government.  This 
is  true  in  the  sense  that  it  is  today  essential  in  all  states,  popular  and  despotic 
alike,  Even  in  a  democracy,  it  is  the  branch  through  which  government  acts 
as  an  evercontinuing  process,  and-  in  which  the  overwhelming  majority 
of  public  employees  work  and  the  vast  bulk  of  public  funds  15  jjpent.  Yet 
policy-making  through.  representative  assemblies  remains  primary.  To  allow 
administrators  to  make  the  policies  they  arc  to  execute,  as  was  the  case  in 
Hitler's  Germany  and  Mussolini's  Italy,  is  the  definition  of  despotism.  To 
organize  government  so  that  controlling  authority  is  always  vested  in  those 
whom  the  people  desire  to  exercise  political  power,  as  is  the  case  in  demo- 
cratic Britain,  under  a  cabinet  backed  by  a  majority  in  the  House  of  Com- 
mons —  this,  many  believe,  is  one  of  the  best  formulas  for  freedom  yet 
devised. 

Where,  as  in  the  United  States,  the  executive  branch  with  its  mix- 
ture of  political  influence  and  administrative  authority  is  largely  independent 
of  the  legislature,  and  where  men  without  political  status  may  suddenly  be 
appointed  to  important  administrative  posts,  ^  special  obligations  rest  on 
administrators  —  as  on  legislators  —  to  maintain  a  sense  of  proportion  about 
their  functions.  Public  executive^  are  obliged  to  engage  in  the  formulation  of 
adminhtratiy£.^poUcy,  and  the  necessity  for  this  should  be.  freefy-jconceded. 
Except  as  the  chief  executive  may  direct,  however,  their  participation  in  the 
making  of  political  policy  should  be  confined  to  advising  him  and  the  legis- 
lature on  policy  matters  in  their  own  field  of  operation  and  offering  recom- 
mendations or  technical  assistance  to  be  used  for  legislative  action.  Here 
the  administrator  may  argue  with  foresight,  with  ingenuity,  and  with  a 
sense  of  urgency.  Having  presented  his  views,  however,  he  has  done  every 
thing  he  may  properly  do. 

Thus  th|gi^at^afl^-^--p^^V--has  its 


It  is  up  to  the  administrator  to  abide  by  them  no  less  than  the  politiciar 
and  the  citizen.  No  bureaucrat  has  been  prevented  from  resigning  his  office 
and  agitating  as  a  citizen  for  the  policies  he  thinks  indispensable  to  th< 
common  welfare.  Nor,  indeed,  is  there  any  law  to  keep  him  from  running 
for  Congress  or  the  state  assembly  or  the  city  council  and,  as  a  politician 


54  BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION 

advocating  what  the  legislature  should  do.  That  is  the  democratic  way  to 
secure  the  enactment  of  a  particular  public  policy— by  winning  a  triumph 
for  it  in  the  political  arena.  That  is  the  reason  why  the  public  takes  offense 
at  men  who,  as  administrators,  would  try  to  "decree"  policies  they  had  been 
unable  to  "put  across"  as  politicians. 

v  Procedural  Rigmarole.  Red  tape — or  what  the  average  citizen  has  in 
mind  when  he  uses  that  phrase — also  supplies  part  of  the  explanation  for  the 
stereotyped  conception  of  bureaucracy.  The  point  should  be  granted  without 
argument.  To  thr  ninety  per  cent  of  the  public  who  want  to  do  "the  right 
hing"  and  generally  know  how  to  do  it,  many  government  procedures 
nust  seem  unnecessarily  complicated.  This  is  true  especially  of  those  to 
whom  it  fails  to  occur  that  most  of  the  detailed  requirements  relating  to  such 
matters  as  permits,  licenses,  and  contracts  are  to  save  the  majority  from  the 
ignorance,  selfishness,  or  carelessness  of  the  other  ten  per  cent.  Hard  and 
costly  social  experience  accounts  in  the  main  for  specificities  of  bureaucratic 
procedure. 

When  at  the  threshold  of  World  War  II  motormaker  William  Knudsen 
assumed  a  post  of  great  importance  in  the  defense  effort  of  the  nation,  he 
said  of  Washington  red  tape,  "In  Detroit  we  call  it  system."  Thus  he  not 
only  gave  it  a  fair  and  simple  characterization  but  he  also  furnished  a  clue 
to  the  reason  why  it  is  productive  of  irritation.  After  all,  it  is  tape,  it  is 
system.  Being  inanimate,  it  is  incapable  of  perfect  and  instantaneous  adapta- 
tion to  every  individual's  personal  interest  or  situation — let  alone  his  whims 
and  fancies.  Resenting  authority  to  begin  with,  man  resents  it  even  more 
when,  no  matter  what  the  reason,  it  seems  to  blind  itself  to  the  scene  of  its 
^operation.  Yet  in  countless  instances  this  appearance  can  hardly  be  avoided. 
There  are  numerous  types  of  situations  in  which  the  power  to  fix  general 
rules  must  necessarily  be  centered,  while  information  relevant  to  their  just 
and  proper  utilization  lies  largely  at  the  point  of  application.  Delegation 
of  discretion  may  not  always  be  a  feasible  answer.  When  public  administra- 
tion has  to  rely  on  absentee  authority,  it  must  accept  the  consequences  in 
popular  resentment  and  dissatisfaction  as  a  "risk  of  operation" — just  as,  in 
similar  circumstances,  they  are  accepted  in  private  business. 

The  assembly  lines  in  the  great  automobile  plants  are  designed  to  move 
at  the  speed  and  in  the  order  that  will  enable  the  workers  to  produce  the 
maximum  number  of  cars  per  day.  This  does  not  mean  that  a  customer  will 
always  be  able  to  get  the  car  he  wants  when  he  wants  it  and  at  the  price 
he  thinks  right — or  that  individual  workers  will  not  find  the  pace  incon- 
veniently fast  or  slow.  So  with  the  red  tape  of  a  government  agency. 
Though  designed  to  enable  its  employees,  working  at  an  established  rate,  to 
provide  the  public  with  service  conforming  to  acceptable  standards,  it  will 
fail  to  meet  precisely  the  needs  of  every  single  citizen.  Methods  and  proce- 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  55 

dures  calculated  to  yield  the  greatest  good  for  the  greatest  number  patently 
cannot  fit  the  details  of  each  and  every  case.2 

Subjectivity  and  Objectivity.  "Bureaucracy"  would  not  signify  to  the 
common  people  the  evils  it  does  in  America  today  were  it  not  that  various 
interests,  unwilling  to  accept  public  control,  have  been  resolved  to  discredit 
if  possible,  the  very  idea  and  institution  of  governmental  administration. 
The  economic  stakes  involved  in  such  efforts  are  great,  and  the  financial 
resources  available  to  support  them  are  frequently  on  the  same  scale.  Much 
of  the  mspiraTipn  fo^  the  battle  against  "bureaucratic  regimentation"  is 
generated  by  nothing  nobler  than  the  desire  tojuake  jt  clifHcult  Or  impossible 
for  democracy  jx)jyiact  or  enforce^  regulations  needed  Jo  protect  the  public 
interest.  Bureaucracy  is  besmirched  because  this  seems  to  offer  an  effective 
way  of  winning  the  battle. 

Through  distortion  and  caricature,  the  term  "bureaucracy"  has  come  to 
imply  bungling,  arbitrariness,  wastefulness,  officiousness,  and  regimentation. 
What  is  its  technical  meaning?  In  free  translation,  it  means  simply  "desk 
government" — management  by  bureaus.  It  denotes  tKe  sum  Jotal^of  the 
personnel^ apparatus^ang~prbceHuFes  by  which  anjpjganizat^n_manages  its 
work  and  achieves  its  purposes.  The  orgamzatipnjnay_bejg»ublic^»r  private, 
governmental,  commercial,  educational,  ecclesiastical — but  if  it  is  of  any 
size  it  must  be  a  bureaucracy. 

In  this  sense,  bureaucracy  is  a  feature  of  all  large-scale  undertakings, 
being  simply  the  means,  human  and  physical,  through  which  they  strive  to 
attain  their  objectives.  From  this  standpoint,  the  General  Motors  Corporation 
is  no  less  bureaucratic  than  the  United  States  Government — and  General 
Motors  employees  are  quite  as  well  aware  of  the  fact  as  are  federal  workers. 
There  is,  however,  a  more  restricted  meaning  of  the  term.  Without  implica- 
tion of  invidious  distinctions,  it  is  confined  in  some  contexts  solely  to  gov- 
ernment. When  so  used  it  normally  refers  to  the  entire  executive  establish- 
ment, especially  the  permanent  or  career  personnel  and  their  operating  facili- 
ties and  procedures.  On  its  administrative  side,  then,  the  whole  problem 
of  government  consists — as  Carl  J.  Friedrich  has  properly  emphasized — in 
the  development  and  maintenance  of  a  bureaucracy  that  is  competent,  re- 
sponsive, and  responsible.3 

2.   THE  SOURCES  OF  RED  TAPE 

Efficiency  in  administration  depends  at  bottom  upon  devising  and  direct- 
ing a  routine,  a  regimen,  a  system.  We  may  grant  that  it  is  never  possible 


2  For  a  provocative  study  through  a  management-engineering  approach  to  the  problem  of 
red  tape,  see  Juran,  J.  M.,  Bureaucracy — A  Challenge  to  Better  Management,  New  York:  Harper, 
1944. 

8  See  his  Constitutional  Government  and  Democracy,  Boston:  Little,  Brown  &  Co.,  1941; 
also  Friedrich,  C.  J.  and  Cole,  Taylor,  Responsible  Bureaucracy:  A  Study  of  the  Swiss  CM 
Service,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1932. 


56  BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION 

to  reduce  all  components  of  a  process  to  the  point  where  they  can  be  so 
handled.  It  is  nevertheless  the  aimJn  all  managenrient  tojliscoyer  and  intro- 
duce that  division  of  spccializcdJ.abQr_.which  will  enable  the  total  job  to  be 
performed  mo§tliti^ctprily  and  at  the  lowest  possible  cost. 

Red  Tape  and  Green  Tape.  From  the  standpoint  of  efficiency,  public 
.ind  private  administration  are  basically  alike.  They  operate  under  similar 
types  of  managerial  motivation  and  compulsion.  Many  of  the  sources  of 
red  tape  in  governmental  bureaucracy  are  no  different  from  those  which 
account  for  the^  "green  tape" — if  we  may  call  it  that — in  business  bureauc- 
racy.4 But  the:  paralleljjojds  true  for  only  part  ofjhcjvay.  Administrators 
in  government  arc  obliged  jo^c_j^gardfuL  of_some  considerations  beyond 
those  to" which  business^an_lim]tjt:s_.  concern.  These  make  the  government 
tape  jcdJjHstf M\  .oL^grecn, .  Typically  they  are  social — Aristotle  would  have 
called  them  political — considerations  as  distinguished  from  economic,  and 
they  certainly  should  figure  in  public  administration. 

Perhaps  in  some  fields  the  ultimate  objectives  of  public  management 
are  identical  with  those  of  commercial  undertakings,  but  this  is  the  excep- 
tion rather  than  the  rule.  Government  generallyjiims  at  ends  more  complex 
and  more  iioy^n£ible_  th^^busi^ess.  Men  look  to  government  for  justice, 
law,  peace,  and  order;  for  the  maintenance  cf  liberty,  equality,  and  oppor- 
tunity; for  impartiality  in  the  enforcement  of  economic  regulations  and 
for  even-handed  ness  in  the  administration  of  economic  assistance — not  so 
much  for  service  that  is  swift  and  cheap  as  for  service  that  is  safe  and  sure. 
They  want  such  service  to  be  economically  efficient.  They  also  want  it  to 
satisfy  these  other  and  more  basic  expectations.  They  do  not  run  their  gov- 
ernment to  make  money.  They  run  it  in  order  to  establish  and  preserve 
an  environment  in  which  they  themselves  can  make  a  decent  living.  The 
ct-nnjnj-^  nf  gtirw»<;g  in  fondness  js ;  tjicj^rcatest^conomic  gnjjTjr>  the  individual 
entrepreneur  or  firm  at  the  lowect  cconomjc  art.  The  standard  for  govern- 
mejit  is Jthe  greatest  ^nri^^nd^conomic  gam  for  the  public  jat  the  lowest 
social-and-economic  or  t  to  all. 

Requirements  of  Efficiency.  To  avail  itself  of  the  economies  latent  in 
specialization  and  large-scale  organization,  government  no  less  than  busi- 
ness must  subnrt  to  the  compulsion  of  working  out  a  detailed  requence 
of  steps  in  which  the  various  jobs  on  each  unit  of  production  can  best  be 
done.  Assembly-line  techniques  offer  marked  advantages  over  those  of 
custom  craftsmanship.  JHey  also  have  their  price.  They  entail  the  imposi- 
tion of  an  order  of  progression,  the  fixing  of  a  rate  or  rhythm  of  operation, 
and  the  discipline  of  a  regular  routine.  Set  order,  fixed  pace,  and  adherence 
to  routine — these  are  the  very  stuff  of  which  red  tape  is  made.  Yet  they  arc 
of  the  essence  of  system,  too. 

4  For  an  amusing  and  withal  an  instructive  account  of  what  can  happen  when  a  customer 
gets  entangled  in  the  green  tape  of  private  business,  see  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  pp. 
58-59,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  57 

Predictability  of  Performance.  Also  common  to  both  government  and 
business  is  the  desire  for  predictability  of  performance.  Both  for  his  own 
peace  of  mind  and  in  the  interests  of  maximum  productivity,  an  adminis- 
trator wants  and  needs  to  know  how  many  units  of  goods  or  services  his 
staff  or  plant  can  produce  per  week  or  per  month  and  at  what  cost.  Whether 
in  government  or  business,  his  only  hope  for  such  predictability  lies  in  the 
possibility  of  maintaining  sufficient  regularity  of  operations,  both  qualita- 
tively and  quantitatively,  to  permit  the  calculation  of  results  in  advance  of 
their  occurrence.  Yet  the  very  regularity  for  which  he  strives  and  on  which 
he  depends  for  his  success  may  prove  detrimentally  monotonous  to  the 
workers  under  him  and  may  not  be  appreciated  by  his  customers. 

These  two,  however,  are  not  the  only  common  sources  of  red  or  green 
tape.  Both  kinds  of  tape  are  nourished  by  institutional  inertia  and  indiffer- 
ence wherever  either  is  allowed  to  gain  a  foothold.  Both  flourish  wherever 
the  lure  of  order,  once  established,  invests  every  precedent  with  the  sanctity 
of  final  authority.  Both  positively  luxuriate  wherever  management  becomes 
so  attached  to  the  comfort  of  accustomed  routine  that  it  avoids  at  all  costs 
even  the  momentarily  disruptive  effects  of  a  slight  change  in  procedure. 

Government  of  Laws.  What  of  the  red  tape  peculiar  to  public  adminis- 
tration? We  may  first  note  the  administrative  counterpart  of  that  key 
principle  in  democratic  politics  which  insists  that  freedom  means  a  govern- 
ment J>f_Jaws  rather  than  of  men.  Public  administration  wears  red  tape 
because  it  is  expected  to  proceed  according  to  objective  rules  rather  than 
the  subjective  intuition  of  government  officials.  Who  would  have  it  other- 
wise? Red  tape  is  perhaps  the  best  insurance  the  public  has  that  all  citizens 
will  receive  equal  treatment  at  the  hands  of  their  civil  servants. 

Accountability  to  the  PMblfc.  Another  closely  related  source  of  red  tape  is 
the  ins.sTenceToFthe  public  on  full  accountability  in  governmental  manage- 
menfTnot "alone Tor  final  results  but  also  for  each  and  every  step  by  which 
they  are  attained.  This  means  that  bureaucrats  arc  required lo-daAcir  work 
in  such  ^\vay  that,  actually_orjxinLngeJitly^  their  every  move  is  open  to  public 
scrutiny._Thcy  must  perform  their  task  in  a  fashion  that  can^b£_defended 
and  justified  even  if  brought  under  the  most  minute  and  critical  review.  The 
result  is  what  might  be  expected — almost  as  much  concern  at  times  over 
not  doing  anything  wrong  as  over  trying  to  do  something  right.  To  make 
matters  worse,  the  tangible  rewards  for  creative  imagination  are  likely  to 
be  meager.  Business  management  prides  itself  on  paying  handsomely  for 
initiative  and  invention.  In  public  administration,  the  premium  on  con- 
structive innovation  is  hardly  ever  of  comparable  magnitude.  Nor  is  this 
for  the  reason  that  governmental  management  does  not  appreciate  the 
value  of  such  incentives.  The  trouble  lies  in  its  being  hedged  about  by  re- 
strictions that  practically  preclude  it  from  using  them. 


58  BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION 

3.  THE  CHARGE  OF  DESPOTISM 

Having  essayed  an  explanation  and  evaluation  of  the  red  tape  and  inef- 
ficiency ascribed  to  bureaucracy,  let  us  now  examine  the  merits  of  two 
graver  indictments— those  of  despotism  and  regimentation.  Both  relate  to 
supposed  abuses  of  trust  or  power  by  the  executive  branch  of  government. 
For  the  sake  of  convenience  we  shall  confine  ourselves  in  the  present  section 
mainly  to  the  charge  that  bureaucracy  seeks  to  usurp  the  judicial  function, 
and  endeavor  thereafter  to  investigate  the  claim  that  it  is  contriving  to  usurp 
the  legislative  function  as  well.5 

Effects  of  the  Industrial  Age.  The  separation  of  powers  has  never  meant 
the  same  thing  in  Britain  as  in  America,  particularly  with  regard  to  rela- 
tions between  the  executive  and  legislative  branches.  However,  with  respect 
to  relations  between  the  executive  and  judicial  branches  it  has  had  approxi- 
mately the  same  significance.  One  of  the  common  assumptions  in  both 
countries  has  been  that  the  rights  and  liberties  of  the  citizen  would  not  be 
secure  unless  all  men,  public  officials  and  private  persons  alike,  were  under 
the  "rule  of  law"  guaranteed  by  a  hierarchy  of  independent  courts  of  law. 
So  long  as  government  could  operate  on  the  scale  of  policing  activity,  the 
judicial  tribunals  were  able  to  dispose  of  nearly  all  types  of  questions  calling 
for  adjudication — whether  arising  out  of  criminal  offenses  in  the  usual 
sense,  civil-law  transactions,  or  noncompliance  with  administrative  regula- 
tions. As  the  impact  of  technology  upon  society  became  more  pervasive, 
every  government  has  been  obliged  steadily  to  extend  the  range  of  its  con- 
cerns. For  the  proper  handling  of  various  types  of  technical  controversies, 
this  has  carried  with  it  the  creation  outside  the  judicial  branch  of  novel 
administrative  agencies  or  tribunals  staffed  with  specialized  personnel  and 
authorized  to  employ  such  procedures  as  might  be  most  effective  in  the 
light  of  the  subject  matter  involved. 

Because  they  were  in  the  vanguard  of  industrialization,  America  and 
Britain  have  had  to  make  changes  in  administrative  structure  and  procedure 
comparable  to  those  undertaken  by  other  nations  which  were  less  deeply 
attached  to  the  ideal  of  the  rule  of  law.  As  in  the  case  of  most  departures 
from  old  ways,  the  new  administrative  tribunals  did  not  always  function 
perfectly,  particularly  in  their  early  years.  Occasionally  they  made  errors 
of  procedural  propriety  which  but  for  subsequent  review  by  courts  of  law 
might  have  led  to  miscarriage  of  justice.  From  the  beginning,  however, 
certain  groups  within  the  body  politic  have  been  unwilling  even  to  acknowl- 
edge the  necessity  for  new  instrumentalities  of  this  kind.  By  insisting  that 
the  rule  of  law  was  being  vitiated  rather  than  aided  by  constructive  adjust- 

5  For  a  fuller  treatment,  sec  below  Part  IV,  "Responsibility  and  Accountability." 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  59 

ments  in  the  manner  of  its  application,  they  condemned  these  instrumentali- 
ties as  agencies  of  a  new  despotism.6 

Charge  of  Usurpation.  Lord  Hewart,  a  British  jurist,  articulated  the 
opposition  in  his  volume  entitled  The  New  Despotism.  His  book  has  had 
so  great  a  vogue  on  both  sides  of  the  Atlantic  that  it  may  well  be  taken 
as  the  definitive  indictment.  "A  little  inquiry,"  he  wrote,  "will  serve  to  show 
that  there  is  now,  and  for  some  years  past  has  been,  a  persistent  influence 
at  work  which,  whatever  the  motives  or  the  intentions  that  support  it  may 
be  thought  to  be,  undoubtedly  has  the  effect  of  placing  a  large  and  increasing 
field  of  departmental  authority  and  activity  beyond  the  reach  of  the  ordi- 
nary law."7  Taking  for  granted  the  adequacy  of  "the  ordinary  law"— per- 
haps more  accurately,  "the  ordinary  courts" — and  thus  in  a  way  begging  the 
whole  question,  the  author  averred  that  the  people  of  Britain  were  in 
danger  of  losing  their  liberties  through  the  growth  of  administrative 
absolutism. 

Hewart  ignored  the  inconvenient  question  of  the  competence  of  the  ordi- 
nary judges  to  ascertain  the  facts,  let  alone  their  significance,  over  a  wide 
range  of  technical  matters.  He  simply  argued  that  individual  rights  and 
liberties  were  now  in  jeopardy  because  the  "ardent  bureaucrat"  had  lately 
come  to  operate  under  "some  such  faith"  as  this:8 

1.  The  business  of  the  Executive  is  to  govern. 

2.  The  only  persons  fit  to  govern  are  experts. 

3.  The  experts  in  the  art  of  government  are  the  permanent  officials, 
who,  exhibiting  an  ancient  and  too  much  neglected  virtue,  "think  them- 
selves worthy  of  great  things,  being  worthy." 

4.  But  the  expert  must  deal  with  things  as  they  are.    The  "four- 
square man"  makes  the  best  of  the  circumstances  in  which  he  finds 
himself. 

5.  Two  main  obstacles  hamper  the  beneficent  work  of  the  expert. 
One  is  the  sovereignty  of  Parliament,  and  the  other  is  the  rule  of  law. 

6.  A  kind  of  fetish-worship,  prevalent  among  an  ignorant  public, 
prevents  the  destruction  of  these  obstacles.   The  expert,  therefore,  must 
make  use  of  the  first  in  order  to  frustrate  the  second. 

7.  To  this  end  let  him,  under  Parliamentary  forms,  clothe  himself 
with  despotic  power,  and  then,  because  the  forms  are  Parliamentary, 
defy  the  Law  Courts. 

8.  This  course  will  prove  tolerably  simple  if  he.  can  (a)  get  legisla 
don  passed  in  skeleton  form,  (b)  fill  up  the  gaps  with  his  own  rules, 
orders,  and  regulations,  (c)  make  it  difficult  or  impossible  for  Parliament 
to  check  the  said  rules,  orders,  and  regulations,  (d)  secure  for  them  the 


6  For  a  fair  sample  of  the  literature  in  which  this  view  is  presented,  sec  Hewart  of  Bury, 
The  New  Despotism,  New  York:  Cosmopolitan  Book  Corp.,  1929  (reissued  London:  Benn, 
1945);  Allen,  C.  K.,  Bureaucracy  Triumphant,  London:  Oxford  University  Press,  1931;  Amer- 
ican Bar  Association,  "Report  of  the  Special  Committee  on  Administrative  Law,"  Reports  of  the 
American  Bar  Association,  1936,  Vol.  61,  pp.  720-794;  McGuire,  O.  R.,  "Administrative  Law 
and  American  Democracy,"  American  Bar  Association  Journal,  1939,  Vol.  25,  p.  393  ff. 

1  Hewart  of  Bury,  op.  cit.,  p.  5. 

id.,  pp.  13-14  (by  permission  of  the  publisher,  Farrar  &  Rinchart,  New  York). 


60  BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION 

force  of  statute,  (e)  make  his  own  decision  final,  (f)  arrange  that  the 
fact  of  his  decision  shall  be  conclusive  proof  of  its  legality,  (g)  take 
power  to  modify  the  provisions  of  statutes,  (h)  prevent  and  avoid  any 
sort  of  appeal  to  a  Court  of  Law. 

9.  If  the  expert  can  get  rid  of  the  Lord  Chancellor,  reduce  the 
Judges  to  a  branch  of  the  Civil  Service,  compel  them  to  give  opinions 
beforehand  on  hypothetical  rases,  and  appoint  tbem  himself  through  a 
businessman  to  be  called  "Minister  of  Justice,"  the  copingstone  will  be 
laid  and  the  music  will  be  the  fuller. 

If  all  this,  or  even  the  main  part  of  it,  were  generally  true  of  democracy's 
bureaucrats  and  their  intentions,  it  would  be  a  devastating  indictment. 
America  and  Britain  would  assuredly  be  en  the  road  to  despotism.  But 
the  charge  is  not  true;  and  for  the  most  part  it  13  wholly  without  warrant.9 
Had  Hewart  and  our  American  critics  of  like  mind  been  content  to  specify 
some  of  the  cautions  which  ought  to  be  observed  in  adapting  the  rule  of 
law  to  the  conditions  of  a  technological  civilization,  they  could  have  per- 
formed a  valuable  service.10  Lacking  both  such  interest  and  moderation, 
what  they  have  done  is  to  prove  too  much. 

Legislative  Delegation.  As  Pennock  observes  in  opening  his  study  of 
Administration  and  the  Rule  of  Law?1  "Before  the  days  of  the  automobile 
there  was  no  need  for  policemen  to  direct  traffic.  Before  our  population 
had  multiplied  and  become  concentrated  in  congested  urban  areas,  sanitary 
inspectors  were  not  so  necessary  as  they  are  now.  Before  the  development 
of  large-scale  business  enterprise,  the  sale  of  securities  required  no  super- 
vision by  the  government."  These  changes  illustrate  some  of  the  technical 
problems  with  which  public  administration  has  been  confronted  through  the 
progress  of  applied  science.  It  is  almost  axiomatic  that  no  invention  is 
ever  quite  an  unmixed  blessing.  New  mechanisms  or  processes  often 
bring  new  dangers  as  well  as  new  utilities.  They  pose  for  government  the 
question  of  how  best  to  secure  public  advantages  without  at  the  same  time 
disturbing  or  endangering  the  social  order  out  of  proportion  to  actual 
gains. 

Ordinarily,  as  might  be  expected,  the  legislative  body  was  the  first  to 
take  positive  action  in  dealing  with  new  situations  of  this  kind.  Generally 
it  has  waited,  sometimes  procrastinated,  until  sufficient  evidence  had  ac- 
cumulated to  demonstrate  clearly  that  existing  prescriptions  and  procedures 

9  For  a  point-by-point  rebuttal  of  Hewart's  charges  in  terms  of  British  bureaucracy,  sec 
Finer,  Herman,  The  British  Civil  Service,  ch.  7,  London:   Fabian  Society  and  Allen  &  Unwin, 
1937. 

10  For    tempered    studies   of    the   problem    of   administrative   adjudication,   see   Pennock, 
J.  Roland,  Administration  and  the  Rule  of  Law,  New  York:   Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1941;  Blachly, 
F.  F.  and  Oatman,  Miriam  E.,  Administrative  Legislation  and  Adjudication,  Washington:   Brook- 
ings  Institution,  1934;  Dickinson,  John,  Administrative  Justice  and  the  Supremacy  of  Law  in 
the  United  States,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1927;  Landis,  James  M.,  The  Adminis- 
trative Process,  New  Haven:    Yale  University  Press,   1938;  Cushman,  Robert  E.,  The  Inde- 
pendent Regulatory  Commissions,  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press,  1941. 

H  See  note  10. 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  61 

were  inadequate  to  protect  the  public  interest  or  safeguard  individual 
welfare.  However,  f^JpS!^aflirp  did  «*f  forth  **  hrst  it  could  the  criteria 
of  the  common^good,  and  thenjvested  the  power  to  apply  those  criteria 
either  in  sojme^administrative  agency  within  the  executive  bran^.o£mZnew 
agency  independent  of  iF^an^norMally  independent  of  the  judicial  branch 
as  well.  Far  from  forsaking  the  ideal  of  justice,  however,  what  the  legis- 
lature had  in  mind  in  assigning  such  tasks  was  to  bring  novel  responsibilities 
of  government  within  a  more  resilient  rule  of  law,  one  ensuring  more  sub- 
stantive knowledge  for  judgment,  simpler  and  swifter  in  procedure,  and 
less  expensive  to  the  litigant,12  yet  withal  equally  just.  In  brief,  legislators 
only  sought  to  cope  with  the  practical  problem  of  devising  ways  and  means 
for  the  equitable  and  expeditious  settlement  of  a  mounting  mass  of  tech- 
nical cases  and  controversies. 

Flexibility  of  Statutory  Standards.  It  is  difficult  to  devise  criteria  and 
standards  for  new  fields  that  will  be  acceptable  as  squaring  fully  with  those 
to  which  in  familiar  situations  men  have  grown  accustomed.  Instead  of 
pretending  to  a  knowledge  they  have  lacked — and  could  not  have — legis- 
lative bodies  have  had  the  wisdom  to  vest  in  specialized  tribunals  and 
comparable  agencies  the  general  responsibility  for  deciding  what  specific 
requirements  would  be  right  or  reasonable  in  their  particular  fields.  vJR>cc: 
ognizing jthat_a^dcgrcc..oL.discretion- hadlo  hf  .rIgrsH  sorn*MirVwfl  in  ruling 
witlTnew  issues,  legislatures  have  conferred  ..it.  .at  kast  for  rhr  ..purpose  of 
establishing  the^  relevant  facts,  upon  officials  possessed  of  technical  knowl- 
edge."OFcourseT  such  officials  were  required  to  observe  fundamental  rules 
of  evidence  in  their  work.  Thus,  statutes  defining  standards  have  used  such 
phrases  as  "reasonable  rates,"  "public  convenience  and  necessity,"  "un- 
reasonable discrimination,"  "action  necessary  or  desirable  in  the  public 
interest,"  "adequate  facilities  and  services,"  "maintenance  of  a  fair  and  orderly 
market,"  and  the  like.13  Interpretation  of  these  phrases  has  been  left  largely 
to  the  regulatory  agencies,  and  as  a  last  resort  to  the  courts. 

Quasi-judicial  Agencies.  By  1946,  Congress  had  established  six  major 
quasi-judicial  agencies  outside  the  executive  branch:  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  1887;  Federal  Trade  Commission,  1914;  Tax  Court  of  the 
United  States,  1924;  Federal  Communications  Commission,  1934;  Securities 
and  Exchange  Commission,  1934;  and  National  Labor  Relations  Board, 
1935.  The  national  legislature  had  also  enacted  scores  of  regulatory  measures 
calling  for  the  exercise,  under  appropriate  rules  of  procedure,  of  consider- 
able discretion  by  administrative  officials  within  the  executive  branch. 
State  legislatures  have  found  it  advisable  to  follow  a  similar  course  within 

12  In  their  concern  for  the  preservation  of  the  rule  of  law,  bench  and  bar  have  tended 
to  ignore  the  matter  of  the  costs  of  justice  to  the  litigant  in  terms  of  both  time  and  money, 
especially  the  latter.  Its  importance  as  a  factor  in  the  creation  of  administrative  tribunals  has 
been  considerable,  in  America  and  abroad. 

!8  Sec  Pennock,  op.  cit.t  p.  31. 


62  BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION 

their  jurisdiction;  so  have  the  municipal  councils  in  every  large  city  through- 
out the  land.  And  the  end  is  not  yet.  Although  the  question  of  whether  to 
vest  such  discretion  in  agencies  within  or  outside  the  executive  branch  is 
still  a  moot  one,  American  experience  witb^administrativc  tribunals  is  by 
now  sufficiently  broad  and  vaiiedLfor  some  generaLconcIusions.  Those 
who  have  studied- it .  jnost  carefully  are  generally  agreed  that  both  the 
graduaMos^by^the^  courts  of  their  former  uncontested  control  over  public 
administration  and  the  par tial^rcjglacemeat. .  of  ) udicial  guarantees  by  ad- 
ministrative guarantees  ot  "liberty  under  law"  have  jiot  ^brought  the  citizen 
un"der  a  new"3espotism.  Oh  the  contrary,  without  the  aid  of  such  agencies 
he  might  'Have  been  unable  to  maintain  his  liberties  against  the  powerful, 
though  impersonal,  forces  which  have  been  rising  about  him.14 

Administrative  tribunals  are  here  to  stay;  the  problem  is  how  to  perfect 
them.  This  comes  down  largely  to  the  question  of  how  to  improve  their 
personnel.  Ideally,  perhaps,  most  of  the  professional  staff  of  a  regulatory 
agency  should  have  a  mastery  of  both  the  technical  subject  matter  with 
which  it  deals  and  the  legal  principles  and  procedures  that  govern  such 
matters  as  the  conduct  of  hearings  and  the  taking  of  evidence.  However, 
these  are  two  distinct  specializations,  and  few  would  be  specialists  in  both. 
The  legal  profession,  as  it  becomes  reconciled  to  the  need  for  administra- 
tive adjudication,  naturally  believes  that  the  best  way  to  secure  a  proper 
balance  between  private  rights  and  public  interests  in  the  regulatory  proc- 
ess would  be  through  stress  on  legal  training.15  Yet  lawyers  should  not 
be  allowed  to  substitute  their  judgment  on  technical  matters  for  that  of 
subject-matter  experts.  Obviously,  the  practical  course  for  every  agency 
of  administrative  justice  to  take  is  to  staff  itself  with  personnel  of  both 
types  and  make  sure  that  consideration  is  given  to  both  sets  of  factors. 

14  For  a  more  specific  discussion,  sec  below  Ch.   10,  "Independent  Regulatory  Establish- 
ments." 

15  Much  pertinent  information  is  to  be  found  in  the  reports  of  the  United  States  Attorney 
General's    Committee   on    Administrative   Procedure,   Washington:    1940-1941;    the    report  on 
Administrative  Adjudication  in   the  State  of  New  Yor^,  submitted  to  Governor  Herbert  H. 
Lehman  by  Robert  M.  Benjamin  and  staff,  1942;  and  the  Tenth  Biennial  Report  of  the  Judicial 
Council  of  California  to  the  Governor  and  the  Legislature,  1944.   Some  indication  of  the  num- 
ber and  variety  of  state  administrative  agencies  engaged  at  least  partially  in  adjudicatory  work 
may  be  gained  from  the  following  list  of  agencies  described  by  the  California  Judicial  Council 
as  conducting  "formal,  adjudicatory  licensing  and  disciplinary  proceedings":    Board  of  Dental 
Examiners,   Board   of  Medical   Examiners,   Board   of  Os»teopathic  Examiners,   Board   of  Nurse 
Examiners,  Board  of  Optometry,  Board  of  Pharmacy,  Board  of  Public  Health,  Department  of 
Public  Health,  Board  of  Examiners  in  Veterinary  Medicine,  Board  of  Accountancy,  Board  of 
Architectural  Examiners,  Board  of  Barber  Examiners,  Board  of  Registration  for  Civil  Engineers, 
Registrar  of  Contractors,  Board  of  Cosmetology,  Board  of  Funeral  Directors  and  Embalmers, 
Structural  Pest  Control  Board,  Yacht  and  Ship  Brokers  Commissioner,  Secretary  of  State,  State 
Fire  Marshal,   State   Mineralogist,   Director  of  Agriculture,   Labor  Commissioner,   Real  Estate 
Commissioner,  Commissioner  of  Corporations,  Department  of  Social  Welfare,  Department  of 
Institutions,   Board   of  Pilot   Commissioners   for   the   Bays  of  San   Francisco,   San   Pablo  and 
Suisun,  Board  of  Pilot  Commissioners  for  Humboldt  Bay,  Board  of  Pilot  Commissioners  for  the 
Harbor  of  Saij  Diego,  Fish  and  Game  Commission,  Board  of  Education,  Board  of  Equalization, 
Insurance  Commissioner,  Building  and  Loan  Commission. 


BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION  63 

In  taking  leave  of  the  alleged  decline  of  freedom  in  the  New  Levia- 
than, we  can  perhaps  do  no  better  than  record  the  considered  opinion  of 
Blachly  and  Oatman  of  the  legislative  proposals  advanced  by  the  American 
Bar  Association  in  the  late  1930's  for  additional  judicial  safeguards  against 
abuses  of  discretion  by  administrative  agencies.  "It  appears,"  they  ob- 
served, "that  the  'tendencies  toward  administrative  absolutism'  so  feared 
by  certain  promoters  of  the  American  Bar  Association  bill  are  largely 
nonexistent."16 

4.  THE  BATTLE  AGAINST  REGIMENTATION 

Parallel  to  the  accusation  that  bureaucracy  has  been  usurping  the  func- 
tion of  the  courts  runs  the  charge  that  it  has  also  encroached  upon  the 
legislature.17  Administrative  adjudication  does  indeed  have  a  counterpart 
in  administrative  rule-making.  Most  of  those  who  dam'n  the  new  despotism 
are  therefore  also  prone  to  denounce  bureaucratic  "regimentation." 

Experience  Abroad.  It  may  conduce  to  a  sounder  analysis  of  American 
developments18  to  look  first  at  Britain  and  France,  democratic  countries  both. 
As  to  the  latter,  the  essence  of  the  matter  can  be  stated  readily.  The  French 
are  logical  and  practical  about  the  need  for  administrative  rule-making, 
as  they  are  about  many  other  things.  Under  the  Republic,  every  statute 
of  consequence  enacted  by  the  national  parliament  included  a  section 
to  the  effect  that  "an  ordinance  of  public  administration  shall  deter- 
mine the  measures  proper  for  securing  the  execution  of  the  present  law."19 
The  French  legislature  had  no  qualms  about  conferring  upon  adminis- 
trators the  task  of  settling  points  of  detail  in  public  policy. 

The  British  attitude  toward  what  they  call  "delegated  legislation"  is  not 
described  as  easily.  Although  there  is  in  England  greater  readiness  to 
accept  the  necessity  of  administrative  regulations  than  in  the  United  States, 
the  House  of  Commons  has  concerned  itself  with  this  matter  no  less  than 
three  or  four  times  in  the  past  generation.  On  the  first  occasion,  with 

1<J  Blachly,  F.  F.  and  Oatman,  Miriam  E.,  Federal  Regulatory  Action  and  Control,  p.  277, 
Washington:  Brookinps  Institution,  1940.  This  matter  is  taken  up  more  fully  below  in  Ch. 
23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 

17  Condemnations  of  bureaucracy  on  the  ground  of  regimentation  may  be  found  in  such 
books    as   Beck,   James   M.,    Our    Wonderland  of  Bureaucracy,   New   York-   Macmillan,    1933; 
Edmunds,  Sterling  E.,  The  Federal  Octoptis,  Charlottes villc:   Michic  Co.,  1932;  Hoover,  Herbert, 
The  Challenge  to  Liberty,  New   York:    Scnbncrs,    1934;   Lane,   Rose  Wilder,   The  Discovery 
of  Freedom:    Man's  Struggle  Against  Authority,  New  York:    John  Day,  1943;  Wriston,  Henry 
M.,  Challenge  to  Freedom,  New  York:    Harper,   1943;  and  Sullivan,  Lawrence,  Bureaucracy 
Runs  Amuck,  New  York:  Bobbs-Merrill,  1944. 

18  For  objective  studies  of  the  need  for  and  the  use  of  delegated  legislation,  see  Andrews, 
John  B.,  Administrative  Labor  Legislation,  New  York:    Harper,   1936;  Blachly  and  Oatman, 
op.  cit.  in  note  16;  Comer,  John  P.,  Legislative  Functions  of  National  Administrative  Authorities, 
New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1927;  Hart,  James,  The  Ordinance-Making  Powers  oj 
the  President  of  the  United  States,  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1925. 

10Ogg,  Frederic  A.,  European  Governments  and  Politics,  p.  451,  New  York:  Macmillan, 
1944. 


64  BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION 

Stanley  Baldwin  at  the  helm  as  Prime  Minister,  the  criticism  of  the  House 
was  "rejected  out  of  hand,"  in  the  words  of  the  London  Times.  The 
Donoughmore  Committee  on  Ministers'  Powers  recommended  in  its  re- 
port20 a  closer  scrutiny  by  Parliament  of  the  promulgation  of  subordinate 
legislation  by  the  executive  branch;  this  led  to  no  significant  action.  Again, 
during  the  early  part  of  World  War  II,  a  similar  proposal  was  offered  but 
was  rejected  by  the  government  on  the  ground  that  its  enactment  would 
becloud  ministerial  responsibility.  In  1944,  however,  it  was  acknowledged 
by  the  government  that  additional  safeguards  should  be  adopted.  Not  least 
of  the  reasons  was  the  belief  that  in  the  future,  ministers  might  have  to 
issue  rules  and  orders  in  greater  volume  than  ever  before.  The  Commons 
took  up  a  motion  to  create 

a  Select  Committee,  .  .  .  whose  duty  it  should  be  to  carry  on  a  continuous 
examination  of  z\\  statutory  rules  and  orders  and  other  instruments  of 
delegated  legislation  presented  to  Parliament;  and  to  report  from  week 
to  week  whether  in  the  opinion  of  the  committee  any  such  instrument 
is  obscure  or  contains  matter  of  a  controversial  nature  or  should  for  any 
other  reason  be  brought  to  the  special  attention  of  the  House. 

This  motion  was  countered  by  Home  Secretary  Herbert  Morrison  with  a 
generous  offer  to  go  even  further. 

Parliamentary  Review  of  Delegated  Legislation.  By  its  terms  of  refer- 
ence the  select  committee  is  charged  with  guarding  the  powers  of  Parlia- 
ment and  the  liberties  of  the  citizen  by  inquiring  into  the  character  and 
effect  of  the  most  important  types  of  delegated  legislation.  Though  lacking 
authority  to  send  for  ministers,  it  can  ask  for  the  services  of  departmental 
officers  in  getting  answers  to  technical  questions  and  securing  other  rele- 
vant information.  This  saves  it  from  having  to  draw  the  attention  of  the 
House  to  a  regulation  without  first  consulting  with  the  department  con- 
cerned. The  committee  chiefly  examines  measures  which  would  impose 
charges  on  the  public  revenues,  require  payments  or  services  to  any  national 
department  or  agency  of  local  government,  or  be  immune  from  challenge 
in  the  courts.  Two  classes  of  orders  are  to  come  in  for  special  scrutiny. 
The  first  includes  all  orders  and  regulations  which  by  law  do  not  become 
effective  unless  approved  by  affirmative  resolution  of  Parliament.  The 
second  and  larger  group  consists  of  rules  and  orders  which  automatically 
go  into  force  unless  opposed  by  a  prayer  or  a  negative  resolution.21  On 
this  basis  the  British  are  prepared  to  go  ahead  and  make  presumably  not  less 
but  more  use  of  delegated  legislation  than  they  have  in  times  past. 

Like  Britain  and  France,  the  United  States  is  part  and  parcel  of  Western 
democratic  and  capitalistic  civilization.  Nothing  is  more  essential  to  the 
health  of  this  civilization  than  the  maintenance,  by  such  governmental 

20  London:  H.  M.  Stationery  Office,  1932,  Cd.  4060. 

21  Cf.  London  Times,  May  16,  1944,  and  the  article  entitled  "Delegation"  in  the  Man- 
chester Guardian,  May  18,  1944. 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  65 

action  as  may  be  necessary,  o£  an  adequate  measure  of  social  and  economic 
equality  among  the  people  and  a  substantial  degree  of  competition  among 
business  enterprises.  The  British  and  the  French  nations  have  been  obliged 
during  the  past  century  to  enact  a  vast  pile  of  legislation  designed  to  main- 
tain such  conditions  within  their  borders;  so  has  America.  And  the  com- 
plexities of  industrial  society  being"  everywhere  much  the  same,  Congress 
has  had  to  assign  the  drafting  of  the  detailed  regulations  implementing 
these  statutes  to  the  administrative  officials  charged  with  their  enforcement — 
just  as  have  the  House  of  Commons  and  the  Chamber  of  Deputies. 

Ignoble  Partisanship.  This  is  the  general  setting  for  bureaucratic  "legis- 
lating" which  has  given  rise  to  the  charge  of  regimentation.  Congress, 
state  legislatures,  and  city  councils  have  placed  upon  administrative  agencies 
responsibility  for  putting  the  flesh  of  life  and  action  on  the  bare  bones  of 
skeleton  legislation  and  for  making  particular  statutes  and  municipal  or- 
dinances attain  the  purposes  behind  their  enactment.  The  bureaucrats 
proceed  as  best  they  can  with  these  difficult  tasks  only  to  find  themselves 
accused  of  all  manner  of  evildoing.  Why?  Because,  as  often  as  not,  having 
been  unable  to  prevent  the  passage  of  the  statute  itself,  those  opposed  to 
its  objectives  have  retreated  to  their  last  line  of  defense  and  have  endeavored 
on  procedural  grounds  to  win  a  battle  already  lost. 

Thus  the  stark  facts  are  frequently  simple — and  on  occasion  they  may 
be  sinister.  Legislative  deliberation  may  reveal  so  great  a  need  for  regu- 
latory action  in  a  given  field  that  the  only  possible  way  left  by  which  the 
opposition  may  hope  to  stave  off  the  imposition  of  controls  is  through  con- 
fusing the  issues.  This  is  precisely  what  is  often  done.  Clearly,  the  real 
parties  to  the  argument  over  public  regulation  of  economic  activity  are  the 
representatives  of  the  people  in  the  legislature  and  the  spokesmen  for  the 
interest  groups  which  desire  to  avoid  the  social  discipline  such  regulation 
would  place  upon  them.  It  is  in  many  instances  the  calculated  intention 
of  those  who  raise  the  cry  of  regimentation  to  befuddle  the  general  public 
into  thinking  that  the  issue  lies  instead  between  tyrannical  bureaucrats  on 
the  one  side  and  well-meaning  citizens  on  the  other. 

Tactics  of  this  kind  have  always  been  used  by  groups  endeavoring  to 
evade  social  obligations.  There  is  no  reason  for  expecting  that  they  will  not 
be  used  until  the  end  of  time.  Of  all  the  fictions  about  bureaucracy,  one 
of  the  greatest  lies  in  the  contention  that  it  is  the  bureaucrats  who  are  re- 
sponsible for  the  imposition  of  governmental  controls  on  economic  activity. 
Such  controls  are  established  by  the  duly  chosen  political  representatives 
of  the  whole  people.  The  much-maligned  bureaucrat  is  but  the  instrument 
through  which  they  are  made  effective. 

Matrix  of  a  Mixed  Economy.  The  abuses  and  insecurities  which  inevi- 
tably result  when  men  insist  on  using  liberty  as  though  it  were  license  have 
forced  an  almost  continuous  retreat  from  the  philosophy  of  governmental 
nonintervention  in  the  economic  sphere.  The  American  economy  is  a 


66  BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION 

mixed  economy.  Private  and  public  undertakings  intermingle.  "Either — or" 
studies  of  the  role  of  government  in  economic  life  have  value  only  in  point- 
ing out  the  perils  of  going  to  extremes.22  Many  aspects  of  production  and 
distribution  can  be  competently  handled  by  private  enterprise  under  law 
and  regulation.  Others  are  so  basic  to  the  maintenance  of  public  health, 
comfort,  and  decency  that  their  management  cannot  safely  be  entrusted  to 
those  who  would  have  to  operate  under  the  limitations  inherent  in  the  profit 
motive.  In  between  lie  fields — and  the  area  is  rather  extensive — which  lend 
themselves  equally  well  to  private,  public,  cooperative,  or  combined  efforts. 

Experimental  Accommodation.  How  far  public  ownership  and  opera- 
tion need  to  be  carried  and  how  far  governmental  regulation  of  private 
enterprise  will  have  to  go  are  certainly  not  questions  which  bureaucrats  will 
be  allowed  to  answer.  Fundamentally,  these  are  matters  of  high  public  pol- 
icy. No  one  can  predict  with  certainty  what  functions  of  regulation  or 
control  governmental  management  will  be  performing  a  generation  hence. 
This  does  not  mean,  however,  that  no  clues  are  available  to  suggest  what  the 
future  will  bring.  It  is  quite  evident  that  we  arc  not  following  any  clear 
line  of  theory  that  would  enable  us  to  anticipate  impending  development. 
We  do  have  the  light  that  comes  from  the  lamp  of  experience,  and  for  a 
people  as  pragmatic  as  ours  that  should  be  a  very  good  light.  The  likeli- 
hood of  socialism  is  at  a  minimum.  We  shall  go  on  in  the  future  as  in  the 
past,  doing  what  viable  governments  have  always  done — gradually  adapting 
forms  and  processes  to  changing  conditions  and  circumstances. 

In  our  long  record  of  evolutionary  rather  than  revolutionary  adjustment 
there  should  be  quite  a  little  reassurance  for  those  inclined  to  be  anxious 
about  the  morrow.  It  should  be  sufficient  to  keep  them  from  rejecting  the 
universe  and  the  century  in  which  they  live.  The  volume  of  governmental 
regulation  of  economic  activities  is  doubtless  destined  to  expand  further. 
Such  gradual  expansion  would  spell  regimentation  only  if  we  allowed  our 
sense  of  social  responsibility  to  deteriorate  and  die. 

5.   THE  NEED  FOR  UNDERSTANDING 

Democracy,  it  is  agreed,  rests  on  understanding  between  the  citizen  and 
his  government.  If  this  is  to  have  any  real  meaning  it  is  equally  essential 
that  there  be  understanding  between  the  citizen  and  his  civil  servants, 
inasmuch  as  most  of  the  citizen's  contacts  with  his  government  are  through 
administrative  personnel  rather  than  through  political  officials.  Obviously 
the  maxim  should  work  both  ways;  the  bureaucrat's  need  to  understand 
the  citizen  matches  the  citizen's  need  to  understand  the  bureaucrat.  As  a 


22  The  year  1944  saw  the  publication  of  two  volumes  that  illustrate  only  too  well  the 
limitations  of  the  either — or  kind  of  analysis:  Miscs,  Ludwig  von,  Omnipotent  Government, 
New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press,  1944;  and  Hayek,  F.  A.,  The  Road  to  Serfdom,  Chicago: 
University  of  Chicago  Press,  1944.  For  a  vigorous  rejoinder,  see  Finer,  Herman,  The  Road  to 
Reaction,  Boston:  Little,  Brown  &  Co.,  1945.  Cf.  also  Wootton,  Barbara,  Freedom  under 
Planning,  Chapel  Hill:  University  of  North  Carolina  Press,  1945. 


BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION  67 

practical  matter,  however,  the  more  urgent  necessity  in  the  present  age  is 
for  greater  public  understanding  of  the  administrative  process. 

Psychology  of  Public  Employment.  Consider  the  ordinary  man  or 
woman  "working  for  the  government."  The  government  worker  is  recruited 
from  no  special  rank  or  class  or  circle  within  American  society;  his  back- 
ground is  the  same  as  that  of  the  average  citizen.  He  is  increasingly  obliged 
to  give  objective  proof  of  competence — first,  to  get  his  job,  and  thereafter  to 
gain  promotion  or  advancement.  His  compensation  may  be  sufficient  to 
enable  him  to  support  his  family  on  an  acceptable  scale  of  living  but  it  is 
never  of  large  proportions. 

He  does  his  work  hedged  about  by  a  mass  of  rules  and  regulations  which 
have  -  accumulated  over  the  years  as  the  embodiment  of  popular  attitudes 
toward  the  conditions  of  public  employment.  Much  of  what  he  does  may 
be  floodlighted  at  any  time  by  pitiless  publicity;  all  of  it  is  subject  to  the 
most  intensive  and  pervasive  scrutiny.  His  chances  of  taking  advantage  of 
society  in  furtherance  of  his  own  ends  should  he  be  so  minded,  arc  fewer 
and  more  circumscribed  than  are  those  of  thousands  upon  thousands  of  his 
fellow  citizens  who  arc  privately  employed. 

Yet  why  presume  that  he  will  be  so  minded?  In  the  first  place,  no  per- 
son desiring  to  lay  his  hands  on  material  riches  would  be  attracted  to  the 
public  service.  The  majority  of  government  employees  are  engaged  in  such 
work  because  the  positions  offered  them  held  the  promise  of  being  "good 
jobs,"  or  at  any  rate  fair  ones.  It  is  not  only  a  mistake,  but  even  an  injustice, 
not  to  remember  that  the  bulk  of  them  are  public  servants  because  that  is 
what  they  want  to  be — because  the  idea  of  serving  the  community  through 
its  government  appeals  to  them  as  the  best  of  all  ways  to  make  their  living 
and  to  spend  their  lives. 

For  these  public  servants  the  taking  of  an  oath  of  loyalty  merely  formalizes 
a  resolution  already  made.  It  amounts  to  an  outer  expression  of  an  inner 
dedication — the  legal  aspect  of  a  code  of  ethics  by  which  the  public  em- 
ployee is  guided  in  all  his  official  acts  and  by  which  he  expects  all  his  fellow 
workers  to  proceed.  An  administrative  official  no  more  seeks  his  position  in 
order  to  be  able  to  sit  in  arbitrary  judgment  over  the  public  than  does  a 
judge. 

Let  the  government  business  be  what  it  may,  when  it  comes  before  the 
administrator  for  action,  his  whole  disposition  is  to  ask  himself  a  series  of 
questions  on  this  order:  What  do  the  Constitution  and  the  statutes  say  on 
this  matter?  What  was  the  intent  of  the  makers  of  policy  in  passing  the 
law?  What  discretion  am  I  obliged  or  expected  or  allowed  to  exercise? 
How  can  I  best  exercise  that  discretion  to  promote  and  preserve  the  public 
interest?  There  need  be  little  mystery  about  the  workings  of  bureaucracy 
for  anyone  honestly  interested  in  finding  out  the  facts.  Administrative  offi- 
cials admittedly  make  mistakes  in  judgment  just  as  do  other  human  beings. 
However,  any  intimation  that  the  typical  official  counts  that  week  lost  in 


68  BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION 

which  he  has  not  perpetrated  some  evil  on  the  public  is  as  base  as  it  is 
ludicrous. 

Veil  of  Official  Anonymity.  One  thing  that  would  doubtless  make  it 
easier  for  the  public  to  overcome  its  misconceptions  about  the  civil  service 
would  be  a  better  understanding  of  the  reasons  for  official  anonymity.  There 
are  two  main  aspects  of  the  matter.  One  is  the  maintenance  of  anonymity 
,by  bureaucrats  in  their  capacity  as  advisers  to  their  political  chiefs.  The 
other  is  their  avoidance  of  public  self-identification  as  personalities  tied  into 
the  work  of  governmental  administration.  Let  us  examine  these  two  aspects 
in  reverse  order. 

Any  administrative  system  operating  under  a  government  of  laws  re- 
quires some  degree  of  official  anonymity.  Without  it  there  would  be  no 
way  of  honoring  the  basic  principle  that  administrative  agencies  are  fun- 
damentally the  impartial  and  impersonal  instruments  through  which  gov- 
ernment performs  its  functions.  The  officials  of  such  agencies  are  not 
supposed  to  place  upon  their  actions  the  stamp  of  their  own  individual 
personalities.  On  the  contrary,  their  job  is  merely  to  be  the  efficient  device 
through  which  the  will  of  the  people  finds  tangible  expression. 

Yet  various  difficulties  arise  when  in  his  official  life  the  bureaucrat 
endeavors  not  to  be  John  A.  Smith,  William  B.  Jones,  or  Edward  C.  Brown 
and  tries  instead  to  be  something  like  a  disembodied  executor  of  public 
policy.  For  one  thing,  he  runs  up  against  the  fact  that  though  theoretically 
the  people  want  him  to  control  his  personal  views  or  preferences  and  func- 
tion only  as  "the  Administrator,"  "the  Bureau  Chief,"  "the  Clerk,"  or  "the 
Licensing  Officer,"  many  of  those  with  whom  he  has  to  deal  want  him  to 
handle  their  cases  on  a  "What's-the-law-between  friends?"  basis.  Friends? 
Yes  and  no.  Certainly  it  is  not  an  uncommon  experience  for  administrative 
officials  to  have  citizens  presume  upon  personal  acquaintance  with  them  by 
asking  for  favored  treatment.  And  there  are  always  plenty  of  others  looking 
for  an  opportunity  to  establish  such  acquaintance  so  that  they  may  presume 
upon  it.  The  official's  reaction  is  usually  what  might  be  expected.  Knowing 
that  even  acquiescence  in  such  presumptions  could  be  ruinous,  he  relies  as 
much  as  possible  upon  official  anonymity  to  discourage  them.  He  can  easily 
go  too  far.  Often  his  desire  to  underscore  the  impersonal  character  of  his 
relationship  with  his  citizen-client  may  lead  him  to  excessive  formality  in 
address  and  conduct. 

Basically,  this  is  the  cause  of  the  development  and  usage  by  govern- 
mental officials  of  that  wooden  diction  formerly  known  as  officialese  and 
now  as  gobbledygook.  Percival  Q.  Adams  of  1456  Jefferson  Street,  Missouri- 
ville,  Missouri,  probably  considers  his  application  for  a  license  or  his  tax 
return  a  matter  quite  as  intimate  as  it  is  momentous.  He  does  not  want  the 
licensing  officer  or  the  tax  collector  to  treat  him  as  if  he  were  merely  a 
number.  He  does  not  like  to  see  himself  referred  to  in  the  third  person. 
Nor  does  he  appreciate  the  deliberate  way  in  which  administrative  officials 


BUREAUCRACY— FACT  AND  FICTION  69 

often  seem  to  avoid  speaking  of  themselves  in  the  first  person  when  writing 
him  about  things  for  which  they  are  supposed  to  be  personally  responsible. 
At  its  worst,  officialese  becomes  so  inverted  and  involved  as  to  be  little  short 
of  maddening.  The  bureaucrat  may  think  his  formalities  nicely  calculated 
to  make  the  citizen  "keep  a  proper  distance."  The  citizen  is  more  likely 
to  feel  that  the  bureaucrat  has  built  a  wall  between  them. 

Official  anonymity  also  stems  from  the  bureaucrat's  wholly  understand- 
able desire  to  escape  being  made  the  victim  of  unreasoning  and  indiscrimi- 
nate criticism.  The  body  politic  accepts  years  of  competent  and  faithful 
service  without  comment  or  commendation.  However,  let  a  bureaucrat 
make  some  little  slip  or  merely  be  charged  with  making  one,  and  the 
chances  are  that  he  and  his  agency  will  have  to  pay  a  price  in  loss  of  popu- 
lar support  and  esteem  out  of  all  proportion  to  the  error  done.  Is  it  any 
wonder,  therefore,  that  to  the  bureaucrat  the  public  sometimes  seems  to  be 
a  dangerous  beast  which  should  be  avoided?  There  are  always  people 
anxious  for  their  own  purposes  to  exploit  the  faults  and  shortcomings  of 
the  government  employee.  What  reaction  could  be  more  natural  for  him 
than  to  contrive  to  reduce  his  exposure  to  such  people  to  the  absolute 
minimum? 

Teams  and  Cogs.  Having  considered  the  needs  and  the  uses  of  official 
anonymity  in  the  relation  between  the  official  and  the  citizen,  let  us  look 
at  the  matter  now  from  the  internal  angle,  that  is,  within  the  bureaucracy 
itself.  No  administrative  agency  can  succeed  in  the  discharge  of  its  function 
unless  its  staff  works  as  a  team  or  as  a  related  group  of  teams.  Each  em- 
ployee, of  course,  will  have  his  individual  assignment,  and,  with  regard  to 
his  particular  job,  he  should  to  a  degree  be  on  his  own.  Yet  this  consideration 
must  always  be  subordinated  to  cooperative  needs  so  that  the  net  result 
becomes  an  "organized"  product  embracing  the  whole  work  of  the  agency.23 
Every  member  of  the  staff  must  learn  that  what  he  does  commits  the  agency 
itself  to  some  extent.  How  to  instill  this  essential  discipline  among  all  the 
employees  under  him  and  yet  not  kill  their  spirit  of  initiative  is  one  of  the 
toughest  problems  the  head  of  any  agency  or  the  chief  of  any  unit  has  to 
face — and  it  has  to  be  faced  continuously. 

Not  all  of  those  confronted  with  this  problem  manage  to  solve  it  satis- 
factorily. Some  generate  in  their  staffs  so  great  a  fear  of  committing  the 
agency  to  someth  ng  wrong  that  their  employees  take  refuge  in  a  timidity 
that  keeps  them  from  being  positive  or  effective  about  anything.  Others  may 
require  their  personnel  to  conform  in  their  mode  of  work  to  so  narrow 
and  rigid  a  group  routine  that  all  become  in  practice  little  more  than 
robots,  cogs  on  the  wheels  of  government,  slaves  of  an  asrembly-line.  For- 
tunately, there  are  others  in  directive  or  supervisory  positions  who  exercise 
special  initiative  in  highlighting  for  their  subordinates  the  public  purpose 


28  For  an  elaboration  of  this  concept,  see  Appleby,  op.  cit.  in  note  4,  p.  78  ff. 


70  BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION 

which  the  agency  was  created  to  serve  and  the  specific  services  which  it 
must  render  in  carrying  out  its  responsibilities.  They  endeavor  to  show 
each  employee  precisely  how  and  where  his  job  fits  into  the  whole  effort. 
Finally,  through  the  practice  of  office  democracy  and  active  concern  for  the 
welfare  and  self-development  of  all  employees,  they  prove  to  each  member 
of  the  staff  that  he  is  regarded  as  a  fellow  worker  and  that  his  work  plays 
a  significant  part  in  the  group  enterprise. 

Ethics  of  Political  Counsel.  Official  anonymity  has  its  most  specific  use 
in  concealing  the  identities  of  bureaucrats  in  their  capacities  as  advisers  to 
political  chiefs.  It  is  an  obvious  obligation  of  the  permanent  administrative 
staff,  especially  those  near  the  top  of  an  agency,  to  give  their  political  chief 
the  soundest  advice  of  which  they  are  capable,  and,  under  the  laws,  to 
carry  out  his  policies  with  loyalty  and  efficiency,  irrespective  of  how  much 
or  little  of  their  counsel  he  accepts.  Not  having  the  authority  to  make  pol- 
icy, permanent  staff  or  line  officers  cannot  identify  themselves  with  the 
responsibility  for  making  it.  Only  yesterday  the  professional  bureaucrat 
advised  the  predecessor  of  his  present  political  chief.  On  some  tomorrow  he 
will  be  advising  his  chief's  successor.  If  today  he  is  to  try  as  hard  to  help 
his  present  chief  succeed  as  he  tried  to  help  others  in  the  past  and  as  he 
expects  to  help  still  others  in  the  future,  it  can  only  be  on  the  basis  of  ten- 
dering his  counsel  within  the  four  walls  of  the  agency.  Under  the  protec- 
tion of  anonymity  his  code  of  ethics  calls  for  excluding  from  his  mind  all 
considerations  except  those  related  to  the  policy  program  of  his  political 
chief,  the  public  interest,  and  the  general  welfare. 

Fact  Over  Fiction.  Granted  that  the  government  bureaucracy  contains 
its  share  of  drones  and  dullards,  of  self-servers  and  time-servers,  of  minor 
tyrants  and  soulless  automatons,  these  comprise  all  told  but  a  fraction  of  the 
total.  Man  for  man  and  woman  for  woman,  there  is  not  now  and  there 
never  has  been  any  reason  for  believing  them  to  be  different  from  their 
fellow  Americans  who  are  self -employed  or  work  in  private  industry.  The 
American  bureaucracy  is  now  so  numerous  that  no  citizen  can  indict  it 
without  indicting  the  nation  itself. 

The  fictions  about  bureaucracy  will  go  on  circulating,  but  there  is  rea- 
son to  expect  that  they  will  do  so  at  a  gradually  decreasing  rate.  Year  by 
year  the  circle  of  popular  understanding  will  grow  wider.  As  it  does,  the 
public  will  more  generally  come  to  appreciate  the  limitations  under  which  it 
has  made  its  civil  servants  work. 

American  democracy  has  thousands  of  exceptionally  gifted  and  devoted 
employees  who  not  only  make  no  fuss  about  being  bureaucrats  but  on  the 
contrary  are  proud  of  the  fact  and  grateful  for  their  tasks.  We  can  see  them 
as  a  composite  picture  when  we  think  of  individuals  such  as  these:  a  con- 
fidential adviser  to  the  President  destined  to  die  years  before  his  time  because 
of  refusal  to  reduce  his  labors  in  proportion  to  his  waning  strength;  a 
journalist  endowed  with  unusual  capacity  for  management  willing  to  let 


BUREAUCRACY — FACT  AND  FICTION  71 

his  private  fortunes  slide  in  order  to  aid  in  the  reorientation  of  a  great  de- 
partment; a  lifelong  government  engineer  drafted  to  run  a  top  war  agency 
after  half  a  dozen  industrialists  had  managed  to  get  all  snarled  up  in  it; 
a  brilliant  former  state  utility  commissioner  prepared  to  undergo  periodi- 
cally the  bitterest  vituperation  in  order  to  demonstrate  democracy's  ability 
to  achieve  the  creative  rehabilitation  of  a  river  valley;  a  genius  in  the  per- 
fection of  budgetary  methods  and  the  direction  of  fiscal  operations  who 
never  had  any  other  professional  ambition  than  to  help  his  government 
translate  its  work  program  into  accomplishment  with  the  greatest  possible 
economy  to  the  taxpayer;  a  director  of  an  agricultural  experiment  station 
still  going  strong  after  nearly  forty  years  of  helping  the  people  of  his  state 
in  the  wise  and  responsible  use  of  their  human  and  material  resources;  a 
veteran  city  manager,  demonstrating  through  his  efficiency  and  his  devotion 
to  his  community  the  promise  and  potentialities  throughout  the  nation  of 
a  public-spirited  profession  of  municipal  management;  thousands  upon 
thousands  of  clerks,  secretaries,  and  stenographers  rendering  competent  and 
faithful  service  at  their  jobs  year  after  year. 

These  are  the  bureaucrats  by  whom  the  people  of  the  United  States 
are  served.  It  is  unthinkable  that  the  day  will  not  dawn  when  their  work 
will  receive  the  recognition  it  deserves. 


CHAPTER 


4 


Democratic  Administration 


1.   LEGISLATIVE-EXECUTIVE  RELATIONSHIPS 

Prophets  of  III.  The  men  who  drafted  the  Constitution  of  the  United 
States  had  had  experience  with  both  hereditary  monarchy  and  a  confedera- 
tion in  which  a  legislative  assembly  possessed  exclusive  power.  As  they 
considered  the  kind  of  executive  head  they  wished  to  create,  it  seemed  that 
they  must  choose  between  tyranny  and  anarchy.  Being  sensible  men,  they 
refused  both.  Instead,  they  invented  a  national  chief  executive  with  broad 
powers  who  was  to  be  chosen  periodically  by  majority  vote — and,  as  it 
turned  out,  by  popular  election. 

The  adoption  of  the  Constitution,  of  course,  did  not  end  controversy  over 
the  powers  and  functions  of  the  President.  The  presidency  has  been  popu- 
lar enough  to  last  longer  without  fundamental  change  than  the  office  of 
any  other  chief  executive  in  any  major  nation.  But  many  have  disliked  it, 
feared  its  influence,  and  believed  that  to  protect  our  liberty  we  should 
restrict  its  initiative  and  independence. 

In  recent  years,  the  contest  over  the  powers  of  the  presidency  has  broad- 
ened into  a  debate  over  the  functions  of  the  executive  agencies  of  govern- 
ment and  their  personnel.  In  these  terms,  of  course,  the  issue  is  more  realis- 
tic in  the  light  of  recent  world  history.  It  is  no  single  "man  on  horseback," 
but  a  dominant  party  or  class,  that  can  threaten  a  nation's  liberty.  The 
administrative  personnel  of  all  our  governmental  bodies,  therefore,  may  well 
consider  what  their  role  should  be  in  a  democratic  society. 

Critics  of  the  part  that  present-day  public  administration  must  play  have 
given  administrators  something  to  think  about.  Mr.  James  Burnham,  for 
example,  has  cheerfully  assured  us  that  public  administrators,  along  with 
corporation  managers,  are  going  to  exploit  the  rest  of  us,  who  will  con- 
stitute the  new  proletariat.1  Others,  like  Hayek  and  Mises,  have  warned 

1  Burnham,  James,  The  Managerial  Revolution,  New  York:  John  Day,  1941. 

72 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  73 

that  the  modern  service  state  will  reduce  us  all  to  servility  just  because  we 
have  asked  its  administrators  to  organize  our  welfare  and  security.2 

Such  charges  are  not  new.  These  scholarly  jeremiads,  as  a  matter  of 
fact,  have  a  familiar  and  even  tiresome  ring  to  those  who  have  heard  the 
same  arguments  used,  in  less  academic  language,  in  municipal  politics. 
When  cities,  in  order  to  get  their  streets  paved  or  their  milk  inspected,  hire 
city  managers  or  strengthen  the  powers  of  their  mayors,  plenty  of  out- 
raged critics  usually  protest  that  the  democratic  system  is  being  undermined. 
These  attacks  appear  to  carry  weight  in  proportion  to  the  lack  of  funda- 
mental agreement  over  the  objectives  of  government.  In  cities  where  there 
has  been  little  factional  dispute  over  fundamental  policy,  arguments  of  this 
sort  are  largely  ignored. 

Whenever  they  are  taken  seriously  in  municipal,  state,  or  federal  affairs, 
they  lead  the  public  to  turn  to  the  stock  prescriptions  of  those  who  wish  to 
weaken  the  executive  power — that  democracy  will  be  safeguarded  only  if 
the  legislature  controls  the  details  of  administration  by  statute,  only  if  the 
civil  service  completely  shuns  questions  of  policy  and  leaves  all  initiative 
to  the  lawmakers,  only  if  the  national  government  stays  out  of  state  and 
local  affairs  and  government  in  general  stays  out  of  business.  Yet  no  admin- 
istrative official  can  work  by  these  maxims.  Like  any  other  citizen,  the 
administrator  in  his  particular  sphere  must  be  concerned  about  the  difficulty 
of  giving  democracy  effective  control  over  the  powerful  forces  that  have  been 
set  free  by  science.  If  he  thinks  that  democracy  is  defined  by  the  maxims 
of  antigovcrnmental  politics  and  still  tries  to  do  his  job,  he  is  likely  to  decide 
that  the  management  of  public  affairs  cannot  be  democratic  and  efficient 
at  the  same  time. 

Some  administrators,  no  doubt,  have  come  to  this  defeatist  way  of 
thinking.  Just  as  Lord  Melbourne  thought  that  religion  was  a  fine  thing 
so  long  as  it  did  not  interfere  with  a  man's  private  life,  so  some  govern- 
mental managers  may  think  that  democracy  is  a  fine  thing  so  long  as  it 
does  not  meddle  with  the  management  of  public  affairs.  Nor  is  this  merely 
an  error  of  governmental  managers.  In  advancing  the  old  argument  that 
government  should  be  run  like  a  private  corporation,  certain  political  re- 
formers have  meant  only  that  government  should  be  efficient,  while  others 
have  meant  that  the  way  it  is  run  should  be  none  of  the  public's  business. 

However,  many  of  the  men  and  women  who  have  distinguished  them- 
selves both  as  public  servants  and  as  students  of  politics  have  shown  little 
disposition  to  look  on  politics  as  a  millstone  round  the  neck  of  governmental 
management.  On  the  contrary,  they  understand  that,  in  a  broader  sense, 

2  Hayek,  F.  A.,  The  Road  to  Serfdom,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1944;  Miscs, 
Ludwig  von,  Omnipotent  Government,  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press,  1944.  A  sharp 
dissent  has  been  voiced  by  Finer,  Herman,  The  Road  to  Reaction,  Boston:  Little,  Brown  & 
Co.,  1945.  Sec  als-o  Wootton,  Barbara,  Freedom  under  Planning,  Chapel  Hill:  University  of 
North  Carolina  Press,  1945. 


74  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

efficient  administration  and  democratic  administration  are  one  and  the 


same/* 


In  spite  of  the  defects  of  our  present  system,  we  ought  not  to  overlook 
the  ways  in  which  our  society  has  operated  with  a  comparatively  high  degree 
of  consent  and  a  low  degree  of  compulsion.  These  ways  may  well  offer 
the  public  administrator  more  opportunity  for  enterprising  service,  though 
considerably  less  security  and  immunity  from  criticism,  than  any  political 
Utopia  devised  by  nostalgic  critics. 

Dangers  of  Oversimplification.  The  importance  of  keeping  adminis- 
tration accountable  to  a  representative  body  will  never  grow  less,  no  matter 
how  strong  a  sense  of  professional  responsibility  public  officials  may  develop, 
no  matter  how  exact  may  become  their  standards  of  service.  The  funda- 
mental powers  and  prerogatives  of  the  legislature  are  as  essential  today 
as  they  were  when  men  first  risked  life  itself  to  assert  them.  It  is  hard  to 
imagine  how  a  government  can  be  democratic  unless  its  legislature  is 
elected  periodically  by  a  free  vote;  unless  the  members  of  the  legislature 
and  legislative  proceedings  are  free  of  executive  coercion  and  corruption; 
and  unless  public  officials  administer  their  offices  according  to  the  statutes 
and  spend  money  according  to  the  legislative  appropriations — all  in  an  en- 
vironment of  free  thought  and  free  speech. 

If  we  start  with  such  a  political  assumption,  how  seriously  should  the 
administrator  take  the  argument  that  the  legislature  should  frame  policy 
in  complete  independence  of  the  executive  branch  and  also  assert  its  control 
over  the  details  of  public  affairs? 

It  does  not  make  sense  to  expect  the  legislative  and  executive  branches 
to  work  in  harmony,  and  then  to  condemn  the  legislature  for  too  sym- 
pathetic consideration  of  executive  proposals.  To  some  extent  the  public  is 
led  into  such  inconsistency  by  the  etiquette  of  a  system  of  separation  of 
powers,  in  which  leaders  of  the  legislature  are  likely  to  be  jealous  of  the 
influence  of  the  chief  executive  and  his  agencies.  However,  some  of  the 
most  violent  feuds  over  legislative-executive  relations  in  the  United  States 
have  developed  in  cities  with  council-manager  government,  in  which  the 
city  manager  is  the  appointee  of  the  council  and  has  no  formal  independence 
of  it  whatever.  Perhaps  the  basic  reason  is  that  the  American  people,  con- 
sidering themselves  responsible  for  creating  their  governmental  arrange- 
ments by  rational  acts  of  will,  expect  the  machinery  automatically  to  conform 
to  the  logic  of  charters  and  constitutions.  Obviously,  the  public  docs  not 
police  compliance  with  these  documents  on  its  own  initiative.  However,  the 
legislator  or  official  who  chooses  to  raise  an  issue  of  procedural  relationships 
between  the  branches  of  government  can  usually  count  on  popular  attention. 

There  are  always  reasons  for  raising  such  issues.  The  legislative  oppo- 
sition frequently  finds  it  expedient  to  argue  that  the  party  in  power  is  giving 


3  For  example,  see  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  New  York:   Knopf,  1945. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  75 

up  legislative  prerogatives,  thus  calling  on  the  corporate  pride  of  lawmakers 
to  reinforce  an  argument  of  policy.  In  1944,  for  example,  Democrats  in 
Albany  were  denouncing  the  Republican  majority  of  the  New  York  State 
Assembly  for  subservience  to  Governor  Dewey  while  the  governor's  cam- 
paign captains  were  denouncing  the  Democrats  in  Congress  for  subservience 
to  President  Roosevelt.  Then,  too,  a  lobbyist  likes  to  bolster  his  case  with 
the  phraseology  of  the  classic  attacks  on  tyranny;  a  press  agent  for  a  vested 
interest  can  do  no  better  than  sound  like  Tom  Paine.  And  newspaper 
reporters,  who  seem  to  specialize  in  public  disagreement,  often  find  proce- 
dural issues  the  best  material  available,  in  the  absence  of  consistent 
disagreement  on  policy. 

The  administrative  official  himself  is  hardly  likely  to  be  impressed  by 
these  issues.  By  the  very  nature  of  his  work,  he  is  or  ought  to  be  proof 
against  the  assumption  that  the  legislative  and  executive  branches  are  fun- 
damentally in  conflict.  He  knows  that  all  the  major  aspects  of  his  program 
depend  on  their  general  agreement.  When  he  thinks  in  practical  terms,  he 
has  to  regard  the  mayor,  for  example,  as  being  his  boss  for  some  purposes, 
the  council  for  others.  He  is  realistic  enough  to  understand  also  that  in  a 
great  many  matters  of  administration  or  even  policy  he  must  make  deci- 
sions himself  without  being  under  the  immediate  control  or  guidance  of 
either  the  mayor  or  the  council,  and  that  in  lesser  matters  his  subordinates 
also  must  be  similarly  independent  of  him.  Without  delegation  of  this  kind, 
no  governmental  organization  can  operate. 

It  is  important  for  the  administrative  official  to  keep  his  thinking  straight 
on  the  large  and  rather  obvious  aspects  of  his  relations  with  the  legislature 
and  the  chief  executive.  Clearly,  the  real  problem  is  not  legislative-executive 
relations  as  much  as  the  relationship  between  an  operating  agency,  on  the 
one  hand,  and  the  legislative  body  and  chief  executive,  on  the  other. 

Control  by  Delegation.  Given  sound  relationships,  many  questions  sim- 
ply solve  themselves.  What,  for  instance,  of  the  century-old  complaint  that 
administrative  agencies  are  issuing  too  many  orders,  and  that  the  legislature 
is  giving  up  its  right  to  settle  questions  by  statute?  A  federal  administrative 
official  knows  that  his  bureau  tfow  settles  by  its  own  orders  many  matters 
that  only  a  few  decades  ago  were  the  subject  of  departmental  action,  or 
even  an  order  by  the  President.  As  the  volume  of  work  increased,  the 
numerical  quantity  of  decisions  naturally  increased  in  greater  proportion 
at  lower  levels.  The  practice  of  leaving  minor  matters  to  be  handled  at 
lower  levels  strengthened  the  control  of  the  higher  executive  at  each  level. 
Indeed,  only  a  systematic  practice  of  directing  the  lower  official  to  take 
responsibility  for  details  can  enable  a  higher  official  to  control  him.  The 
sheer  quantity  of  work  to  be  done  by  any  large  organization  makes  such 
selective  delegation  essential  to  administrative  control.  The  same  principle 
must  be  applied  to  legislative  control.  Just  as  the  President  can  direct  the 
executive  branch  only  if  he  concentrates  his  personal  attention  on  the  most 


76  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

important  matters  and  delegates  the  minor  ones  to  others,  so  Congress  can 
determine  national  policy  by  legislation  only  if  it  focuses  on  the  great  issues 
and  leaves  the  lesser  ones  to  be  handled  by  the  President. 

Similarly,  an  executive  is  eager  to  have  his  subordinates  develop  and 
propose  new  policy.  Administration  is  quite  unlike  the  writing  of  poetry  or 
other  forms  of  personal  inspiration;  as  the  old  wisecrack  has  it,  an  adminis- 
trator is  one  who  never  writes  what  he  signs  or  signs  what  he  writes.  This 
is  inevitable  because  the  creation  of  policy  is  a  collective  process — one  of 
gathering  ideas  and  facts  and  combining  them  into  a  program.  When  a 
city  manager  finds  the  proposal  of  a  department  head  acceptable,  it  is  a 
sign  of  good  teamwork;  when  the  council  finds  the  proposal  of  a  city  man- 
ager acceptable,  some  faction  will  surely  accuse  it  of  being  a  "rubber  stamp." 
It  is  time  that  someone  asked  the  obvious  question:  If  a  legislature,  un- 
coerced  and  unintimidated,  agrees  after  open  discussion  with  the  proposals 
of  its  chief  executive,  is  it  not  a  sign  of  effective  democracy  rather  than  of 
shameful  submission?  It  is  pure  romance  to  consider  disapproval  of  a  sub- 
ordinate's recommendation  a  sign  of  independence.  The  effective  super- 
visor— whether  legislative  or  executive — gets  his  policies  carried  out  by 
inducing  his  subordinates  to  develop  and  execute  his  general  program.  To 
do  so,  he  must  reach  an  understanding  with  them  about  his  goals  at  an  early 
stage  in  the  formulation  of  policy,  so  that  he  rarely  needs  to  reject  a  specific 
proposal  and  start  all  over  again. 

A  large  legislative  body  will  always  find  it  difficult  or  impossible,  even 
through  committees,  to  keep  in  touch  with  all  the  advance  planning  of 
administrative  agencies  and  to  control  the  detailed  application  of  policy. 
The  legislator  is  tempted  by  short-run  interest  and  pressure  from  his  con- 
stituents to  make  up  for  this  limitation  by  political  interference  with  mat- 
ters that  for  best  performance  ought  to  be  delegated — the  selection  of  indi- 
vidual officials,  the  location  of  field  offices,  the  letting  or  cancellation  of 
contracts,  the  modification  of  administrative  orders.  This  temptation  is  apt 
to  defeat  the  whole  purpose  of  legislative  supervision,  which  is  to  define  the 
major  lines  of  policy  for  the  executive  branch  to  follow. 

Democracy  and  Legislative  Supremacy.  Let  us  consider  the  classic  exam- 
ple of  parliamentary  government.  It  is  easy  to  see  how  a  legislature  may 
keep  administration  generally  responsive  to  its  control  by  only  the  broadest 
kind  of  supervision.  The  British  Parliament  delegates  far  more  rule-making 
power  to  the  executive  branch  than  would  be  constitutionally  possible  in 
the  United  States.  Among  the  subjects  covered  by  such  rules  is  the  whole 
problem  of  governmental  organization.  The  outlines  of  departments  and 
their  divisions,  and  also  the  membership  and  structure  of  the  Cabinet  itself, 
are  not  fixed  by  legislation  but  by  Orders  in  Council,  Treasury  memoranda, 
or  even  less  formal  documents.  Moreover,  while  the  House  of  Commons 
discusses  the  main  policies  proposed  by  the  Prime  Minister,  it  rarely  alters 
them.  In  effect,  individual  members  acting  for  themselves  cannot  get 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  77 

amendments  to  any  important  legislation  considered  by  the  House,  and 
the  House  has  not  altered  the  executive  budget  during  this  century.  Mem- 
bers of  the  House  have  never  been  able  to  interfere  with  administrative 
details;  by  the  time  that  "His  Majesty's  Service"  became  a  fiction  and  both 
the  Cabinet  and  the  civil  service  came  under  the  control  of  the  House,  the 
doctrine  of  collective  responsibility  of  the  ministers  as  the  Cabinet  induced 
them  to  keep  other  members  of  the  House  from  interfering  with  the  direc- 
tion of  their  departments. 

For  our  purpose,  the  primary  fact  is  that  British  administration  became 
democratic  as  the  legislature  restricted  itself  to  a  very  general  kind  of  super- 
vision. Nor  can  we  consider  it  paradoxical  that  general  legislative  control 
should  be  improved  by  the  prevention  of  legislative  actions  aimed  at  details. 
It  was  one  of  the  main  purposes  of  our  Constitution  to  take  certain  types 
of  executive  actions  out  of  the  hands  of  the  legislature,  breaking  boldly  with 
a  habit  that  had  developed  in  nearly  every  early  state  legislature  and  in  the 
Congress  of  the  Confederation.  As  Thomas  Jefferson  wrote  a  friend  shortly 
before  the  Constitutional  Convention  met,  "I  have  ever  viewed  the  executive 
details  as  the  greatest  cause  of  evil  to  us,  because  they  in  fact  place  us  as  if 
we  had  no  federal  head,  by  diverting  the  attention  of  that  head  from  great 
to  small  subjects."4 

Even  after  the  adoption  of  the  Constitution,  it  was  and  is  still  possible 
for  Congress,  in  sharp  contrast  to  the  House  of  Commons,  to  keep  its  fingers 
on  all  kinds  of  executive  details  through  its  standing  committees.  But  any- 
one who  believes  this  difference  an  inherently  national  one  should  consider 
the  contrast  in  local  government.  General  management  of  British  cities 
rests  with  committees  of  the  city  councils,  council  members  being  elected 
by  wards.  Most  large  American  cities,  and  nearly  all  the  better  governed  ones, 
are  administered  either  by  strong  mayors  or  city  managers,  while  the  indi- 
vidual members  of  the  comparatively  small  councils  do  not  participate  in 
the  direction  of  administrative  affairs.  The  most  delightful  aspect  of  the  mat- 
ter is  that  Americans  are  apt  to  call  the  parliamentary  system  undemocratic 
whenever  they  learn  how  much  power  it  places  in  the  Prime  Minister,  while 
British  municipal  officials  consider  the  city-manager  plan  and  strong-mayor 
plan  quite  dictatorial  and  un-British,  whatever  administrative  merits  these 
plans  may  possess. 

Legislators  Versus  Legislatures.  In  general,  a  legislature  does  not  make 
administrators  responsive  to  representative  control  either  by  settling  details 
in  statutes  or  by  refusing  on  principle  to  support  policies  proposed  by  the 

4  To  Edward  Carrington  from  Paris,  August  4,  1787.  The  Life  and  Selected  Writings  of 
Thomas  Jefferson,  p.  428,  New  York:  Modem  Library,  1944.  However,  even  Jefferson  per- 
mitted himself  moments  of  cynicism.  At  the  age  of  77,  when  recalling  the  Congress  of  the 
Confederation,  Jefferson  wondered  "whether  Bonaparte's  dumb  legislature,  which  said  nothing, 
and  did  much,  may  not  be  preferable  to  one  which  talks  much,  and  does  nothing."  And  he 
added,  "That  one  hundred  and  fifty  lawyers  should  do  business  together,  ought  not  to  be 
expected."  Jefferson's  Autobiography,  in  op.  cit.  p.  61. 


78  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

executive  branch.  This  point  is  often  obscured,  however,  because  a  legisla- 
ture does  not  speak  to  the  public  with  a  single  voice.  Being  composed  of 
a  majority  and  a  minority,  it  may  in  general  stand  behind  the  chief  execu- 
tive, and  at  the  same  time — through  a  vocal  minority  in  control  of  certain 
committees — appear  to  oppose  him  vigorously.  It  is  then  only  natural  for 
the  newspapers  to  give  the  public  the  impression  that  the  executive  branch 
is  carrying  out  a  policy  over  the  opposition  of  the  legislature.  What  is  called 
"executive  usurpation"  often  resolves  itself  into  a  case  in  which  the  majority 
of  the  legislature  fails  to  defend  against  minority  attack  the  policy  that  it 
is  generally  supporting.6 

If  it  is  entirely  democratic  for  an  administrator  to  carry  out  the  intent 
of  the  legislature  in  the  face  of  attacks  from  individual  legislators  or  legis- 
lative committees,  another  point  becomes  apparent.  Representative  control 
can  be  fully  accomplished  only  if  the  chief  executive  and  the  legislature 
work  in  harmony — the  former  to  maintain  effective  control  over  his  depart- 
ments and  bureaus,  the  latter  to  keep  its  individual  members  and  commit- 
tees from  using  tricks  of  procedure  to  block  its  general  program.  The  real 
issue  of  representation  and  responsibility  is  not  simply  between  the  chief 
executive  and  the  legislature,  but  between  the  two,  on  the  one  hand,  and 
each  and  all  of  the  departments,  bureaus,  and  legislative  committees  that 
seek  to  go  their  own  ways,  on  the  other.  The  great  advances  in  attaining 
administrative  responsibility  to  the  legislative  branch  which  have  been 
achieved  in  the  United  States  have  been  made  possible  by  strengthening 
the  chief  executive,  who  alone  can  present  to  the  legislature  a  coherent  pro- 
gram over  and  through  which  broad  and  democratic  control  can  be  exercised. 

In  exercising  such  control,  the  legislature  needs  staff  assistance  in  the 
review  and  interpretation  of  facts,  the  appraising  of  programs,  the  drafting 
of  bills,  and  other  technical  work.  It  must  have  committee  secretariats,  legis- 
lative reference  aids,  and  parliamentary  counsel  to  fit  itself  for  its  tasks  of 
general  surveillance,  just  as  a  chief  executive  needs  the  tools  of  management 
that  are  appropriate  to  executive  control.  However,  the  committee  members 
must  keep  decisions  in  their  own  collective  hands  and  direct  their  staff 
toward  matters  of  proper  legislative  concern.  Any  legislative  staff  that  is 
allowed  to  reach  into  the  particulars  of  agency  operations  becomes  in  effect 
a  rival  administrative  department,  with  all  of  the  power  of  the  executive 
officials  and  none  of  their  responsibility  for  results. 

2.   THE  PUBLIC  AS  STAR  CUSTOMER 

Methods  of  Opinion  Analysis.  A  legislature,  even  if  bicameral,  is  essen- 
tially a  single  body.  As  a  body,  it  can  act  only  on  a  limited  number  of 
important  problems.  Its  influence,  however,  extends  beyond  its  formal  acts. 
An  alert  administrative  agency  does  not  merely  comply  with  statutes;  it 

6 Leigh,  Robert  D.,  "Politicians  vs.  Bureaucrats,"  Harper's  Magazine,  January  1945,  Vol. 
190,  pp.  97-105. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  79 

seeks  to  anticipate  the  drift  of  public  opinion,  to  develop  policy  proposals 
today  that  will  meet  the  legislative  demands  of  tomorrow.  For  this  reason 
it  wishes  to  keep  in  touch  as  closely  as  possible  with  public  opinion.  It  may 
do  so  partly  by  new  and  specialized  methods  of  analysis,  but  it  is  likely 
to  depend  mainly  on  compiling  and  appraising  in  a  systematic  way  the 
information  that  flows  in  as  a  result  of  its  ordinary  operations. 

One  of  the  new  and  specialized  methods  is  the  opinion  survey.  What 
the  marketing  survey  does  for  a  business  organization,  the  opinion  survey 
does  for  administrators  eager  for  the  views  of  the  star  customers  of  the 
government,  the  general  public.  By  investigating  the  techniques  of  the 
American  Institute  of  Public  Opinion,  Congress  has  virtually  recognized 
the  national  importance  of  this  type  of  unofficial  referenda.  As  Dr.  Gallup 
and  his  competitors  keep  in  touch  with  broad  national  issues,  so  public 
agencies  use  similar  polling  techniques  to  keep  informed  of  what  the  general 
public  or  specific  groups  think  of  their  programs.  The  Department  of  Agri- 
culture, for  example,  has  conducted  elaborate  scientific  surveys  of  public 
opinion  with  its  own  specialists,  not  only  for  its  own  use  but  also  for  other 
departments.  Many  cities — notably  Kansas  City,  Missouri,  and  Seattle — have 
made  similar  surveys  with  the  help  of  research  institutes  or  universities,  to 
say  nothing  of  less  professional  studies.  In  addition  to  these  sampling  sur- 
veys, nearly  all  government  departments  study  the  current  trends  in  public 
opinion  as  reflected  in  newspaper  and  trade-journal  comment. 

Advisory  Committees.  Most  administrative  policies,  however,  do  not 
touch  the  public  as  a  whole.  Administrative  agencies  arc,  therefore,  usually 
more  interested  in  the  opinion  of  one  or  another  special  group  that  is  prin- 
cipally affected  by  their  programs.  The  formal  advisory  committee  is  one 
means  of  keeping  in  touch  with  such  opinion.  The  War  Production  Board, 
for  instance,  developed  an  extensive  system  of  such  committees  and  a  set 
of  principles  to  guide  their  operations.  The  principles  themselves  were  not 
new,  for  they  have  been  followed  in  practice  by  many  similar  advisory  com- 
mittees at  all  levels  of  government — and  ignored  by  others.  In  summary, 
they  established  a  procedure  by  which  affected  private  interests  may  be  con- 
sulted by  the  agency,  but  will  not  be  permitted  to  block  action  which  is 
indicated  by  the  public  interest.  The  relationship  between  the  agency  and 
the  affected  interests,  however,  will  not  depend  primarily  on  such  procedures 
or  even  on  the  existence  of  formal  machinery  for  consultation.  Far  more 
important  will  be  the  degree  of  public  support  for  the  purposes  of  the 
agency,  the  effectiveness  of  its  organization  and  operations,  and  the  cohesive- 
ness  of  the  private  interests  and  their  willingness  to  cooperate  with  the 
government.  If  these  conditions  are  favorable,  a  governmental  agency  may 
be  more  intimately  in  touch  with  the  private  interests  than  any  advisory 
group  itself  could  be. 

Day-by-Day  Administrative  Relationships.  Best  of  all  as  a  means  of 
keeping  in  touch  with  the  special  opinion  of  affected  interests  are  the  day- 


80  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

by-day  administrative  relationships.  Through  consideration  of  large  quanti- 
ties of  individual  cases,  officials  may  judge  not  only  the  nature  of  the  opin- 
ions of  those  affected  but  also  their  general  temper.  Of  course,  the  stream  of 
information  between  public  officials  and  citizens  should  flow  both  ways.  One 
of  the  most  curious  aspects  of  the  attacks  on  "bureaucracy"  in  recent  years6 
has  been  the  opposition  to  publicity  programs  or  to  the  spending  of  money 
for  reports  to  the  public,  as  if  it  were  improper  or  undesirable  for  a  govern- 
mental agency  to  ask  for  the  cooperation  of  the  public,  rather  than  to  rely  on 
sanctions.  While  some  agencies  have  developed  programs  of  persuasion, 
especially  in  seeking  compliance  with  requirements  newly  established  by 
statute,  most  have  stressed  straight  information. 

Reporting  to  the  Public.  In  general,  the  quality  of  purely  factual  report- 
ing has  unquestionably  improved.  Cities  have  competed  with  each  other 
to  issue  the  most  informative  and  interesting  annual  reports.  A  few  states 
have  followed  their  example,  and  several  federal  agencies  prepare  periodic 
reports  that  are  encyclopedias  of  information  for  whole  areas  of  our  social 
activities.  The  Yearbook  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture  has  long  been 
an  indispensable  reference  work  in  its  field.7  Nor  is  it  simply  a  matter  of 
providing  information  on  government  programs  for  the  voter  to  weigh  and 
analyze.  Most  useful — and  most  significant  of  the  present  role  of  adminis- 
tration— are  the  periodic  and  special  reports  which  become  the  basis  for 
all  sorts  of  private  activity.  The  weather  reports,  the  census  compilations, 
the  specialized  periodicals  such  as  the  Federal  Reserve  Bulletin,  the  Federal 
Home  Loan  Banf^  Review,  Domestic  Commerce — publications  like  these 
furnish  essential  data  for  many  and  varied  private  operations. 

The  daily  work  of  the  governmental  press  agent,  often  disguised  by 
various  more  dignified  terms,  has  its  place  in  the  total  democratic  process. 
He  is  often  the  closest  and  most  frequent  adviser  of  administrative  officials 
on  the  general  aspects  of  their  programs.  His  bias  is  all  in  favor  of  what 
the  public  will  like,  for  his  success  is  measured  by  the  degree  of  public 
approval  he  wins  for  his  agency.  Too  often  he  thinks  of  advancing  the 
personal  fortunes  of  his  boss,  and  too  rarely  does  he  take  a  long  and  im- 
partial view  of  the  administrative  program.  But  his  shortcomings  are  to 
some  degree  corrected  by  the  independence  of  newspaper  reporters  and 
editors.  His  general  influence  on  administration  is  surely  on  the  side  of 
adjusting  it  to  the  taste  of  the  public. 

Commissions  of  Inquiry.  Advisory  committees  and  public  reporting  have 
their  influence  on  departmental  policies.  Even  more  important  is  the  effect 
on  national  policy  of  programs  developed  by  special  advisory  groups,  in- 

6  Sec  above  Ch.  3,  "Bureaucracy — Fact  and  Fiction." 

7  A  reader  interested  in  the  general  philosophy  of  an  editor  of  government  reports  who 
combines  an  understanding  of  general  public  affairs  with  an  appreciation  of  scientific  techniques 
and — rarest  of  all — a   literary  style  should   read   the   volume  of  essays  by   the  editor  of  the 
Agriculture  Yearbook:   Hambidge,  Gove,   The  Prime  of  Life,  New  York:   Doublcday  Doran, 
1942. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  81 

eluding  both  public  officials  and  private  citizens.  Such  programs  have  no 
mandatory  effect,  but  the  influence  of  painstaking  research  and  thoughtful 
recommendations  may  be  tremendous  in  the  long  run.  Anyone  who  reads 
the  reports  of  President  Hoover's  Committee  on  Recent  Social  Trends  and 
of  his  Commission  on  Home  Building  and  Home  Ownership  will  discover 
in  them  the  outlines  of  the  subsequent  decade's  national  policy  on  social 
welfare  and  housing.  Our  current  policies  are  still  being  influenced  by  the 
reports  of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board,  which  brought  together 
natural  and  social  scientists  and  leading  administrators  from  private  and 
public  life  to  draft  national  programs.  And  as  World  War  II  came  to  an 
end,  we  were  brought  face  to  face  with  a  new  program  outlined  in 
Science:  The  Endless  Frontier,  a  report  prepared  by  Dr.  Vannevar  Bush 
as  director  of  the  Office  of  Scientific  Research  and  Development,  who  under- 
took this  task  at  the  direction  of  the  President  and  with  the  help  of  com- 
mittees including  the  leading  scientists  and  educators  of  the  country. 

The  basic  changes  in  our  national  policy  are  rarely  the  invention  of 
either  legislators  or  administrators  working  alone.  They  reauire  the  con- 
sensus of  interested  men  and  women  of  special  knowledge  and  the  sup- 
port of  private  organizations,  as  well  as  the  agreement  of  officials,  the 
promotion  of  popular  understanding  through  press  and  radio,  and  the 
sanction  of  elected  representatives. 

3.  PUBLIC  PARTICIPATION 

Cooperative  Government.  It  is  hard  to  talk  realistically  about  govern- 
ment as  long  as  we  think  of  it  as  something  apart  from  ourselves.  A  govern- 
mental program  does  not  exist  for  its  own  sake,  but  as  a  part  of  a  larger 
purpose  tied  into  the  social  order.  This  must  be  remembered  when  we 
hear  government  described  as  something  equivalent  to  coercion.  As  a  sam- 
ple of  this  type  of  thinking,  we  may  recall  that  the  National  Association  of 
Manufacturers  proclaimed  at  its  1944  convention  that: 

Government,  in  order  to  be  a  government,  must,  in  the  final  analysis, 
depend  on  the  legal  use  of  force,  and  by  its  very  nature  must  make  this 
force  the  basis  of  its  dealings  with  the  private  citizen.  Under  any  form 
of  government-dictated  economy  this  means  the  intrusion  of  the  irresist- 
ible force  of  government  into  the  everyday  affairs  of  life.  These  intru- 
sions must  be  accomplished  by  those  in  the  employ  of  the  government. 
Such  is  political  bureaucracy,  and  therein  lie  the  seeds  of  tyranny.8 

As  a  general  picture  of  public  administration,  this  statement  needs  to 
be  revised  with  a  touch  of  realism.  Force  wielded  by  government  employees, 
intruding  into  the  everyday  life  of  the  citizen  to  deliver  his  mail,  to  relieve 
him  of  his  garbage,  to  teach  his  children,  to  keep  him  from  driving  on  the 
wrong  side  of  the  road — are  these  "intrusions"?  And  it  may  also  be  asked 

s  As  reported  in  the  New  York  Times.  Dec.  8,  1944. 


82  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

whether  private  corporations  themselves,  and  their  property,  do  not  need 
to  be  protected  and  supported  by  force  wielded  by  government  employees. 
It  is  at  variance  with  fact  to  see  public  administration  as  the  employment 
of  force  against  citizens.  Nor  does  it  make  sense  to  think  of  it  as  being 
controlled  solely  or  even  primarily  by  government  employees. 

When  we  judge  the  political  character  of  public  administration — and  be- 
fore we  decide  that  it  is  either  dictatorially  oppressive  or  enervatingly  pater- 
nalistic— we  should  remind  ourselves  that  nearly  every  main  function  of 
government  is  now  administered  by  cooperation  among  levels  of  govern- 
ment or  between  public  and  quasi-public  or  private  agencies.  Not  only  has 
the  public  become  the  star  customer  of  government,  but  business,  labor, 
and  a  host  of  organized  group  activities  have  all  been  rolled  into  one  com- 
plex cooperative  system.  In  this  system  the  traditional  values  of  liberty  have 
not  been  lost.  Yet  a  higher  degree  of  teamwork  or  harmony  has  been 
attained  than  would  ever  be  achieved  through  a  coercive  approach. 

In  general,  the  system  that  for  want  of  a  better  name  has  sometimes 
been  called  "cooperative  government"  is  one  in  which  a  broad  program  is 
carried  out,  not  by  a  single  national  agency  such  as  the  Post  Office  Depart- 
ment, but  by  federal,  state  and  local  agencies  working  in  cooperation  with 
each  other,  with  quasi-governmental  or  private  institutions,  with  business 
and  labor.  For  its  greatest  efficiency,  cooperative  government  requires  a 
high  degree  of  mutual  trust  and  common  understanding,  harmonious  action 
by  several  or  perhaps  even  thousands  of  legislative  bodies,  and  considerable 
voluntary  support  from  private  individuals  or  institutions. 

Combined  Operations  Among  Levels  of  Government.  One  of  its  aspects 
is  the  cooperation  of  federal,  state,  and  local  agencies  in  almost  all  the 
important  programs  of  government,9  whether  in  education,  social  security, 
agriculture,  public  health,  the  regulation  of  commerce,10  housing,  highways, 
public  works,  or  any  other  fields.  Rather  than  list  the  programs  in  which 
intergovernmental  cooperation  is  essential,  it  would  be  better  to  challenge 
the  reader  to  name  an  important  one  in  which  it  is  not.  He  may  start  with 
the  business  of  the  post  office,  but  he  will  be  hard  put  to  it  to  find  another. 
He  had  better  not  mention  national  defense,  usually  considered  a  predomi- 
nantly federal  function,  until  he  has  studied  the  influence  of  the  state  militia 
and  the  National  Guard  on  our  military  history,  and  the  way  in  which  the 
National  Guard  is  formally  a  part  of  the  structure  of  the  War  Department. 
And  as  national  defense  becomes  more  and  more  a  matter  of  technological 
and  industrial  power,  it  is  significant  that  the  most  basic  scientific  research 
for  national  defense  in  World  War  II  was  conducted  by  private  institutions 


9  Bane,    Frank,    "Cooperative   Government   in   Wartime,"   Public   Administration   Review, 
1942.  Vol.  2,  p.  95  ff. 

10  The  degree  of  cooperation  in  this  field  is  rarely  appreciated.   Cf.  Bosworth,  Karl  A.,  "Fed- 
eral-State Administrative  Relations  in  the  Regulation  of  Public  Service  Enterprises,"  American 
Political  Science  Renew,  1942,  Vol.  36,  p.  21*5  ff. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  85 

— academic  and  industrial  research  laboratories.  These  appeared  better  able 
to  develop  new  secret  weapons  because  they  had  an  independent  status  and 
thus  greater  leeway  in  approach,  even  though  they  were  working  within 
the  framework  of  governmental  policy.11 

The  system  of  cooperative  government  was  greatly  expanded  during 
World  War  II.  Never  before  had  governmental  operations  and  planning 
been  so  decentralized  in  the  United  States  as  at  the  time  when  their  pur- 
pose became  utterly  concentrated  and  their  potential  authority  great  beyond 
any  peacetime  precedent.  The  Selective  Service  System  turned  over  to  local 
boards  of  volunteers,  set  up  by  state  agencies,  the  task  of  manning  the  armed 
forces.  Much  the  same  policy  was  followed  by  our  price  and  rationing 
administration.  And  there  are  other  examples.  If  the  Office  of  Civilian 
Defense  was  no  conspicuous  success  at  the  national  level,  the  civilian  de- 
fense councils  in  many  states  and  thousands  of  communities  served  as  vital 
nuclei  for  tying  together  at  a  lower  level,  and  modifying  in  the  light  of 
local  circumstances,  the  many  national  programs  of  civilian  war  activity. 
Anyone  who  thinks  of  the  war  program  as  something  dictated  from  Wash- 
ington may  study  the  war  activities  of  the  Council  of  State  Governments, 
the  American  Municipal  Association,  and  the  United  States  Conference  of 
Mayors.  State  and  local  governments  not  only  had  to  carry  out  national 
programs  in  many  obvious  and  some  unexpected  ways,12  but  they  were  often 
ahead  of  federal  agencies  in  realizing  and  pointing  to  the  need  for  new 
policies. 

Although  state  and  local  governments  still  use  the  jargon  of  states'  rights 
and  local  autonomy,  in  practice  they  know  that  they  cannot  live  in  inde- 
pendence. They  must  work  with  federal  agencies  and  influence  federal 
activities  in  order  to  justify  their  existence.  A  system  in  which  local  gov- 
ernments with  their  own  legislative  bodies  carry  out  national  programs 
under  the  guidance  of  federal  agencies  has  one  highly  important  general 
advantage — both  political  and  administrative — over  a  completely  national 
system.  The  man  doing  the  job  in  the  service  of  the  locality  has  reason  to 
feel  a  general  responsibility  to  the  public,  not  merely  a  specialized  one  for 
a  particular  branch  of  administration  to  a  distant  superior.  To  be  specific, 
the  city  manager  whose  welfare  department  is  carrying  out  a  function  on 


11  For  an  appreciation  of  the  part  that  state  military  organizations  play  in  Army  affairs, 
see  Palmer,  Brig.  Gen.  John  McAuley,  America  at  Arms,  Washington:  Infantry  Journal  Press, 
1943.     Still  more  relevant  to  modern  warfare  is  the  story  of  the  development  of  the  atomic 
bomb,  radar,  the  proximity  fuse,  and  other  new  weapons.    See  Smyth,  Henry  DeWolf,  Atomic 
Energy  for  Military  Purposes:  The  Official  Report  on  the  Development  of  the  Atomic  Bomb 
under  the  Auspices  of  the  United  States  Government,  1940-1945,  Princeton:  Princeton  Uni- 
versity Press,  1945.     See  also  two  forthcoming  books  on  the  Office  of  Scientific  Research  and 
Development:  Baxter,  James  Phinney,  Scientists  Against  Time,  and  Stewart,  Irvin,  Organizing 
Scientific  Research  for  War,  both  to  be  published  by  Little,  Brown  &  Co. 

12  For  example,  the  provision  of  emergency  war  housing  required  the  amendment  of  city 
building  codes,  and  the  national  fiscal  policy  depended  partly  on  cooperative  state  and  local 
taxing  and  spending  programs. 


84  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

behalf  of  federal  and  state  agencies  is  freer  to  have  an  independent  opinion, 
and  to  express  it  to  the  head  of  the  national  program,  than  if  he  were  a 
local  employee  of  a  national  agency.  To  carry  out  the  function  he  must 
keep  his  legislative  body  informed,  and  its  members  in  turn  may  educate 
their  constituents.  While  doing  the  job  he  can  keep  it  from  colliding  with 
programs  of  other  federal  agencies,  or  v/ith  state  or  local  activities.  In  brief, 
the  cooperative  system  gives  the  man  at  the  level  of  local  government  a 
better  chance  to  weave  together  the  many  strands  of  national  policy  than 
does  a  system  in  which  every  function  has  its  own  special  functionaries 
from  the  top  level  all  down  the  line. 

One  particularly  good  example,  though  in  some  ways  it  is  unique,  is 
the  scheme  of  agricultural  administration.  It  has  been  influenced  by  concen- 
trated economic  forces  to  a  lesser  degree  than  have  comparable  activities 
in  the  fields  of  commerce  and  industry.  As  a  result,  the  traditional  American 
individualist,  the  farmer,  has  retained  wider  opportunities  for  direct  par- 
ticipation in  cooperative  government.  He  has  taken  part  in  the  develop- 
ment of  an  intricate  cooperative  system  of  public  subsidy,  joint  marketing, 
production  control,  soil  conservation,  public  credit,  freely  available  scientific 
research,  and  technical  education  in  state  universities,  extension  courses,  and 
on  the  farm.  From  the  administrative  point  of  view,  this  area  is  especially 
interesting  because  it  illustrates  so  well  how  some  functions  can  best  be 
handled  by  national  agencies,  especially  if  they  deal  with  broad  economic 
problems  like  farm  credit  or  aid  to  underprivileged  groups  like  the  program 
of  the  Farm  Security  Administration;  how  other  functions  are  best  en- 
trusted to  state  agriculture  departments;  others  to  land-grant  colleges;  and 
still  others  to  the  joint  efforts  of  experiment  stations  and  extension  services, 
in  which  the  county  agent  works  at  one  and  the  same  time  for  all  levels  of 
government  and  for  private  associations  of  farmers — and  on  the  side  helps 
carry  on  incidental  programs  of  welfare  and  education.13 

Benefits  of  Intergovernmental  Collaboration.  To  see  the  benefits  of  a 
cooperative  system  it  is  not  necessary  to  believe  that  local  government  is 
closer  to  the  people,  or  more  important  to  the  people,  or  more  democratic, 
than  national  government.  None  of  the  traditional  local  functions  deals 
with  as  many  people  every  day  as  does  the  postal  service;  none  of  them 
affects  the  lives  of  citizens  in  ways  as  important  as  do  international  diplo- 
macy and  war.  And  all  functions  exercised  by  state  and  local  governments 
are  more  likely  to  fall  under  the  control  of  irresponsible  groups,  whether 
wardheelers  or  powerful  economic  interests,  than  is  the  case  in  the  federal 
government.  Moreover,  the  business  of  the  nation  commands  the  citizen's 
first  attention.  The  newspaper  editor  knows  what  people  are  interested  in 

13  For  comments  on  the  type  of  functions  that  are  administered  by  one  level  of  govern- 
ment alone  and  those  that  are  managed  cooperatively,  see  Benson,  George  C.  S.,  The  New 
Centralization,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1941.  See  also  Baker,  Gladys,  The  County 
4gent,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1939. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  85 

when  he  puts  Washington  affairs  on  the  front  page,  and  local  council  news, 
if  any,  inside  with  the  hair-tonic  ads. 

Yet  there  is  a  great  deal  to  be  said  for  arrangements  under  which  public 
officials  with  a  national  point  of  view  have  to  deal  on  a  basis  of  mutual 
respect  with  public  officials  representing  a  local  point  of  view.  Quite  a  few 
broad  governmental  programs  may  well  be  divided  into  specific  functions, 
some  under  exclusive  federal  or  local  control  and  others  under  mixed  con- 
trol, but  with  representatives  of  all  levels  of  government  in  a  position  to 
criticize  independently  the  arrangements,  and  to  speak  up  if  they  are  dis- 
regarded. Even  if  the  federal  government  is  the  exclusive  source  of  funds 
or  has  the  final  word  in  any  dispute,  the  participation  of  local  agencies  may 
be  a  source  of  initiative,  of  independent  criticism,  and  of  administrative 
personnel  who  have  been  trained  in  the  exercise  of  political  responsibility 
rather  than  as  anonymous  components  of  a  larger  organization. 

Inclusion  of  Business  and  Labor.  It  is  interesting  to  note,  moreover, 
how  the  cooperative  system  has  been  extending  itself,  not  only  to  local 
governments  and  public  institutions,  but  to  business  corporations  that  are 
sometimes  thought  to  be  motivated  only  by  their  balance  sheets.  Perhaps 
the  general  drift  toward  the  view  that  private  property,  too,  is  a  public  trust 
is  partly  responsible.  And  perhaps  the  way  in  which  the  management  of 
business  has  become  largely  separated  from  ownership  has  opened  the  road 
to  cooperation  with  the  government. 

This  is  not  to  suggest  that  business  interests  are  sacrificing  themselves 
out  of  public  spirit.  It  is  only  to  say  that  they  now  see  their  place  in  a 
larger  system  more  clearly  than  was  the  case  half  a  century  ago.  They  have 
been  drawn  into  the  administration  of  national  programs  by  the  legislation 
that  they  have  sponsored,  by  regulations  imposed  on  them,  by  contractual 
arrangements  with  public  authorities,  and  through  the  activities  of  their 
trade  associations.  For  example,  in  World  War  I,  the  federal  government 
took  over  the  railroads.  In  World  War  II,  the  Office  of  Defense  Trans- 
portation established  general  policies,  and  the  Association  of  American 
Railroads  served  as  the  go-between  with  the  individual  railways  both  on 
the  formation  of  these  policies  and  their  execution.  That  individual  rail- 
way cars  are  moved  about  the  country  according  to  orders  from  a  national 
center  in  compliance  with  general  governmental  policies  is  not  socialism,  but 
something  that  would  never  have  been  recognized  by  Adam  Smith. 

Property,  as  the  lawyers  say,  is  only  a  bundle  of  rights.  Legislators  and 
administrators,  unlike  doctrinaire  socialists,  have  followed  the  advice  of 
Aesop  by  dealing  with  each  right  separately,  so  that  the  national  interest 
in  the  use  of  property  may  find  expression  while  private  interest  is  not 
destroyed.  There  is  indeed  no  general  principle  about  government-business 
relations  that  is  uniformly  binding.  Like  state  and  local  governments, 
business  enterprise  has  to  justify  its  existence  by  its  usefulness  in  the  public 
interest.  It  would  not  do  to  expect  too  much  of  such  a  general  responsi- 


86  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

bility  by  itself,  but  it  is  probable  that  government-business  relations  will 
be  worked  out  according  to  specific  and  empirical  standards,  field  by  field. 

As  business  corporations  come  into  the  picture,  so  do  labor  unions.  In 
World  War  I,  the  Navy  manned  merchant  vessels  that  carried  supplies  and 
munitions  to  France.  In  World  War  II,  while  the  ships  were  being  oper- 
ated by  private  companies  for  the  War  Shipping  Administration  under  a 
variety  of  contractual  arrangements,  they  were  manned  by  civilians  whom 
seamen's  unions  referred  to  the  companies.  Much  of  the  function  of  pro- 
tecting seamen  that  was  assigned  in  the  late  nineteenth  century  to  a  gov- 
ernment agency — the  Bureau  of  Navigation — has  now  been  taken  over  by 
union  delegates. 

Group  Initiative  Under  National  Standards.  The  modern  tendency  is 
for  the  federal  government  to  see  to  it  that  private  organizations  or  state 
and  local  governments  do  certain  things  according  to  certain  standards, 
instead  of  doing  them  itself.  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Administration,  for 
instance,  licenses  private  flying  schools  and  private  repair  shops  to  examine 
the  pilots  and  inspect  the  maintenance  of  aircraft — functions  comparable 
to  those  which  the  early  Steamboat  Inspection  Service  assigned  to  its  in- 
spectors. Thus  an  agency  empowered  to  establish  its  own  regulations, 
instead  of  being  bound  by  detailed  legislation,  is  apt  to  discover  that  admin- 
istrative effectiveness  dictates  the  same  policy  as  does  the  desire  to  leave 
private  enterprise  independent  of  detailed  government  control,  subject  to 
standards  established  in  the  public  interest. 

In  all  these  cooperative  arrangements,  private  associations  play  an  es- 
sential part.  De  Tocqueville  remarked  a  century  ago  that  the  leadership 
in  public  affairs  which  would  be  assumed  by  a  public  functionary  in  France 
or  a  grand  gentleman  in  England  was  taken  in  America  by  a  private  as- 
sociation.14 Some  of  these  are  organizations  of  people  bound  together  only 
by  public  spirit  and  civic  interest  in  a  single  subject;  some,  like  trade  and 
professional  associations  or  organizations  of  public  officials,  are  bound 
together  by  a  common  occupational  interest. 

It  must  not  be  imagined  that  such  a  system  always  works  toward  the 
public  welfare.  It  has  the  disadvantage  of  diffusing  responsibility  and 
encouraging  various  groups  to  blame  their  own  shortcomings  on  each 
other.  In  some  cities,  for  example,  the  price  of  decent  housing  is  outrage- 
ously high  because  real  estate  men,  dealers  in  construction  materials,  con- 
tractors, labor,  and  local  government  all  work  closely  together  to  force  the 
consumer  to  pay  more  than  he  should.15 

To  keep  the  mai^  lines  of  policy  in  the  hands  of  responsible  public  of- 

14  Democracy  in  Amrrica,  Vol.  2,  p.  106,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 

18  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Investigation  of  Concentration  of  Economic 
Power,  Monograph  No.  8,  Toward  More  Housing,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office, 
1940.  Other  monographs  of  this  committee  illustrate  the  dangers  of  private  exercise  of  what 
amounts  to  governmental  power  in  other  economic  fields. 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTOATION  87 

facials  is  essential  if  a  governmental  program  is  to  be  democratically  ad* 
ministered.  To  let  local  agencies  use  national  funds  for  purposes  other 
than  those  determined  by  responsible  national  authorities,  or  to  leave  to  a 
private  interest  the  responsibility  of  regulating  itself,  cannot  be  justified 
on  any  grounds  of  democratic  decentralization.  However,  the  existence  of 
many  organizations  which  command  the  loyalties  of  citizens  is  the  best 
guarantee  that  no  single  agency  can  demand  and  abuse  that  loyalty.  The 
people  may  safely  call  on  their  governmental  executives  for  vigorous  leader- 
ship as  long  as  they  have  many  channels  through  which  to  contribute  to  the 
development  of  policies  and  to  protest  those  that  seem  to  be  determined 
by  self-interest  or  professional  prejudice. 

4.  REPRESENTING  THE  PUBLIC  INTEREST 

Interdependence  of  Public  and  Private  Interests.  The  system  of  mixed 
governmental  and  private  effort  has  not  solved  all  our  political  and  ad- 
ministrative problems;  sometimes  it  may  seem  that  it  has  only  complicated 
them.  In  politics,  it  has  made  the  old  issues  of  left  wing  versus  right  wing, 
government  ownership  versus  private  enterprise,  appear  unrealistic.  In 
administration,  it  has  added  so  many  dimensions  to  the  functions  and  re- 
sponsibilities of  public  management  that  the  negative  formulas  of  the  nine- 
teenth century  have  been  rendered  inadequate.  The  problem  is  no  longer 
simply  how  to  prevent  special  privilege;  it  is  one  of  organizing  the  larger 
public  interest. 

The  most  conspicuous  kind  of  nineteenth-century  privilege — party 
spoils — is  fast  becoming  obsolete.  The  new  problem  is  more  subtle  than 
the  prevention  of  patronage  in  jobs  or  contracts.  It  is  to  keep  the  system 
of  cooperative  government  from  freezing  into  a  structure  of  guilds  or  com- 
peting pressure  groups.  The  distinction  is  not  mainly  one  of  form  or 
pattern,  but  of  purpose  and  attitude.  We  cannot  solve  the  problem  by 
saying  that  government  must  not  aid  private  interests,  for  the  interests  of 
private  organizations  and  governmental  agencies  are  so  thoroughly  inter- 
twined that  many  of  the  distinctions  between  them  have  become  only 
incidental. 

World  War  II  extended  the  interdependence  of  private  and  public 
interests.  Private  enterprise  was  often  conducted  in  plants  built  by  a  gov- 
ernmental corporation,  with  raw  materials  assigned  by  priorities,  with 
labor  provided  by  the  United  States  Employment  Service,  with  expenses 
covered  by  cost-plus-fee  contracts  or  profits  restricted  by  renegotiation,  and 
perhaps  in  communities  built  by  public  housing  agencies.  But  this  is 
nothing  fundamentally  new  in  America.  It  is  as  old  as  the  land  grants  to 
railroads  and  homesteaders,  as  Henry  Clay's  "American  system"  of  tariffs 
and  internal  improvements,  and  as  the  subsidized  and  chartered  private 
companies  that  established  most  of  the  thirteen  colonies  in  the  New  World 


88  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

while  the  other  Americas  were  being  developed  by  alliances  of  military  and 
ecclesiastic  hierarchies. 

Threefold  Collaboration  in  Policy-Making.  Today  we  see  most  national 
policies — which  govern  the  larger  private  interests  as  well  as  purely  govern- 
mental business — worked  out  in  three-fold  collaboration,  with  participation 
by  congressional  committees,  by  administrative  officials,  and  by  represen- 
tatives of  private  interest  groups. 

It  is  clearly  essential  to  democratic  government  that  the  legislature  be  free 
to  consider  and  reject  the  proposals  of  administrative  officials  and  of  pressure 
groups,  and  that  it  give  no  particular  official  or  private  interest  an  exclusive 
right  to  be  heard.  Yet  the  "bureaucrats"  and  the  "lobbyists"  have  a  vital 
role  in  the  formulation  of  policy,  for  they  shape  up  the  smaller  questions 
into  large  issues  capable  of  legislative  consideration.  Congress  would  be 
faced  with  chaotic  conditions  if,  for  instance,  it  insisted  on  reading  petitions 
from  individual  businessmen  instead  of  hearing  the  testimony  of  trade- 
association  executives. 

To  develop  a  program  in  democratic  fashion,  it  is  indispensable  to  ex- 
amine present  administrative  experience,  study  the  probable  effect  of  new 
proposals  on  all  interests  concerned  and  on  related  programs,  and  then 
subject  the  proposals  to  legislative  hearing  and  debate.  While  the  repre- 
sentative of  the  special-interest  group  plays  a  necessary  part  in  this  process, 
the  public  administrator  has  much  the  same  special  knowledge  and  a 
broader  kind  of  responsibility.  His  role  in  the  formulation  of  policy — for 
final  legislative  consideration,  amendment,  and  approval  or  rejection — is 
and  should  be  an  influential  one.  It  is  accepted  as  such  whenever  any  group, 
in  or  out  of  the  legislature,  tries  to  work  out  a  practical  program.  Heated 
denunciation  of  the  influence  of  bureaucrats  on  legislation  is  usually  only 
a  tactical  maneuver  in  the  battle  over  policy. 

The  administrative  official  has  several  assets  that  make  it  in  accordance 
with  the  public  interest  for  him  to  exert  great  influence  in  the  evolution  of 
policy.  He  may  develop  imoartial  scientific  and  professional  standards 
for  the  measurement  of  the  effect  of  policies.  He  may  judge  the  working 
of  those  policies  by  close  observation  in  actual  practice.  His  enthusiasm 
for  theories  is  likely  to  be  tempered  by  a  shrewd  appreciation  of  what  is 
possible  and  practical  and  what  is  not.  And  yet  he  can  be  the  spokesman  of 
interests  that  are  not  cohesive  or  powerful  enough  to  hire  press  agents  or 
influence  legislators  by  closely  reasoned  arguments.  This  function  is  espe- 
cially important  since  consumers — being  equivalent  to  the  general  citizenry 
—rely  mainly  on  their  government  to  protect  their  interests  against  the 
powerful  lobbies  of  producers  and  salesmen. 

AH  the  advantages  that  the  administrative  official  possesses  in  the  formu- 
lation of  policy  are  reflections  of  the  responsibility  of  his  position.  It  is  his 
task  to  further  the  purposes  defined  by  law  and  executive  order,  which  are 
a  part  of  a  general  program  supported  by  the  dectorate.  He  is  directly 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  89 

accountable  to  his  superiors,  and  indirectly  to  the  legislature,  whost*  control 
over  appropriations  is  a  powerful  weapon  for  the  enforcement  of  responsi- 
bility. His  professional  bias  and  his  governmental  responsibility  alike  impel 
him  to  work  for  the  public  interest.  In  practice,  his  influence  is  considerable. 
Careful  studies  of  the  origins  of  legislation — of  the  sources  of  the  drafts  of 
bills  acted  on  by  the  legislature — show  that  in  federal  and  state  governments 
alike  the  administrative  official  is  accepted  as  the  ghost  writer  of  the 
lawmaker.10 

Informality  of  Policy-Making  Process.  On  the  other  hand,  no  matter 
how  much  of  scientific  methods  or  objective  standards  is  applied  in  the 
development  of  a  policy,  a  public  official  is  subject  to  the  error  of  overempha- 
sizing his  own  specialty.  The  more  zeal  he  shows  for  the  public  welfare, 
the  greater  is  the  probability  of  error.  This  kind  of  distortion  is  increased 
by  the  tendency  of  the  official  to  ally  himself  with  legislators  who  have 
similar  preferences  and  with  interest  representatives  holding  a  similar 
point  of  view. 

Such  informal  alliances  to  further  the  public  interest  by  advancing  spe- 
cial programs  make  it  impossible  to  determine  exactly  who  was  responsible 
for  what.  The  effective  responsibility  for  the  content  of  public  policy  can- 
not be  measured  simply  in  the  number  of  bills  that  are  prepared  by  lobby- 
ists, by  administrative  officials,  or  by  individual  legislators.  For  the  more 
important  decisions  in  the  formulation  of  policy  are  usually  made  in  informal 
discussions  in  which  those  concerned  try  to  work  out  an  agreement  before 
the  proposal  is  formally  prepared  for  legislative  consideration. 

Even  if  no  informal  discussions  are  held,  a  proposal  drafted  by  an  ad- 
ministrative official  will  be  influenced  greatly  by  his  judgment  of  what  the 
legislative  committee  will  probably  accept  and  of  what  will  arouse  strong 
opposition  by  private  interests.  It  should,  therefore,  be  stressed  that  the  very 
fluidity  and  informality  of  this  process  is  its  most  democratic  characteristic. 
The  legislature  and  the  chief  executive  are  enabled,  if  they  consider  it  in  the 
general  public  interest,  to  refuse  to  accept  the  organized  point  of  view  of 
the  interest  group  or  the  administrative  department,  and  to  try  through  other 
combinations  of  private  interests  and  public  administrators  to  line  up  a 
workable  new  program. 

For  while  government  departments  and  organized  private  interests  are 
basic  machinery  in  our  social  system,  they  can  be  positive  forces  in  a  democ- 
racy only  if  they  are  kept  in  line  with  the  general  public  interest.  It  is  not 
enough  for  them  to  refrain  from  encroaching  on  the  rights  of  others;  they 
must  actively  contribute  to  the  general  welfare.  To  enforce  this  fundamen- 
tal responsibility  it  is  necessary  to  prevent  any  single  collection  of  interests — 
whether  a  government  department,  a  trade  association,  a  labor  union,  or 


16Witte,  Edwin  E.,  "Administrative  Agencies  and  Statute  Lawmaking,"  Public  Adminis- 
tration Review,  1942,  Vol.  2,  p.  116  ff.;  Scott,  Elisabeth  M.  and  Zeller,  Belle,  "State  Agencies 
and  Lawmaking,**  ibid.,  p.  205  ff. 


90  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

what  not — from  monopolizing  an  activity  so  completely  that  it  can  deal  with 
the  people  and  their  government  on  its  own  terms. 

Experimental  Approach.  For  this  reason  it  may  sometimes  be  politi- 
cally wise  not  to  consolidate  major  bureaus  or  departments  even  though 
they  have  related  functions,  especially  if  they  are  pursuing  different  experi- 
mental approaches  to  a  problem  and  if  their  consolidation  would  result  in 
dropping  such  productive  experimentation.  Thus  a  two-party  system  is  bet- 
ter than  a  one-party  system,  not  because  the  two  parties  have  different 
philosophies,  but  because  each  helps  prevent  the  other  from  subordinating 
the  general  welfare  to  its  prejudices  and  interests.  Similarly,  at  the  top  level 
of  administration  where  broad  political  considerations  are  properly  involved, 
it  may  sometimes  be  desirable  to  avoid  a  neat  pattern  which  puts  all  related 
functions  under  the  same  agency,  in  order  to  give  the  chief  executive  more 
freedom  of  choice  in  the  future. 

For  example,  in  the  middle  1930's  the  field  of  housing  was  divided  into 
sharply  defined  groups,  each  with  its  own  solution  to  the  housing  problem. 
The  real-estate  boards,  the  building  and  loan  associations,  the  commercial 
banks,  the  lumber  dealers,  the  welfare  workers,  the  advocates  of  decentral- 
ized subsistence  homesteads,  the  advocates  of  slum  clearance — each  of  these 
private  groups  was  sure  that  its  solution  alone  was  right,  each  identified  it 
with  its  own  philosophy,  each  lined  up  in  support  of  an  administrative 
agency  dedicated  to  something  like  its  approach,  each  cultivated  the  Con- 
gressmen whose  committees  were  likely  sources  of  support.  To  amalgamate 
the  various  administrative  agencies  in  the  field  of  housing  at  that  stage 
would  have  been  to  commit  the  country  to  a  partial  approach.  After  eight 
or  ten  years  of  enlightening  experimentation,  however,  all  groups  were  much 
better  prepared  to  admit  the  possibility  of  making  the  several  programs 
operate  in  harmony  rather  than  in  opposition  to  each  other.  It  was  then 
feasible  to  bring  the  several  administrative  establishments  into  a  single  Na- 
tional Housing  Agency,  each  retaining  a  measure  of  its  independence  and 
each  fitting  itself  into  a  comprehensive  program. 

General  Interest  Over  Special  Interest.  The  program  of  a  government  is 
never  merely  the  sum  of  its  departmental  programs;  it  may  be  either  much 
more  or  much  less.  It  is  much  less  if  the  basic  purposes  of  the  departments 
are  inconsistent.  It  is  much  more  if  their  operations  are  linked  together,  each 
furthering  the  activities  of  the  others  and  all  submerging  their  jurisdictional 
disputes  in  a  general  current  of  agreement. 

But  the  legislature  alone  cannot  accomplish  such  administrative  coordina- 
tion. The  democratic  process  of  subordinating  the  special  interest  to  the 
general  interest  depends  to  a  high  degree  on  the  leadership  of  the  chief 
executive  in  the  sponsorship  and  application  of  policy.  No  one  is  in  a  better 
position  to  observe  how  present  developments  will  require  changes  in  policy. 
No  one  else  can  as  effectively  use  the  agencies  of  centralized  management — 
budgeting,  planning,  personnel— to  guide  the  preparation  of  policy  as  well 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  91 

as  its  execution.  No  one  else  can  equally  well  back  up  his  formal  orders 
to  the  executive  establishment  with  administrative  sanctions. 

The  broader  the  responsibility  of  an  administrator,  the  more  concerned 
he  must  be  with  the  general  aspects  of  the  government's  program,  and  the 
less  with  narrow  questions  of  technical  efficiency.  The  specialist  in  manage- 
ment efficiency  or  scientific  research  who  resents  "political"  interference 
from  above  may  be  properly  objecting  to  partisan  exploitation  of  his  job. 
It  is  just  as  likely,  however,  that  he  resents  having  the  technical  aspects  of 
his  work  adjusted  to  fit  a  general  program.  Similarly,  the  bureau  chief 
naturally  dislikes  having  his  aims  subordinated  to  those  of  the  department, 
and  in  turn  the  department  head  may  seek  to  be  as  independent  as  possible 
of  the  chief  executive. 

It  is  plain  that  the  adjustment  of  each  level's  work  to  make  it  fit  into  a 
larger  pattern  is  the  essential  process  in  administration.  As  long  as  this 
process  is  carried  on  in  an  atmosphere  of  free  criticism,  and  with  the  chief 
executive  responsible  to  the  people,  it  is  a  truly  democratic  process.  The 
higher  the  level  at  which  an  administrative  official  operates  and  the  broader 
his  responsibilities,  the  closer  he  is  to  direct  accountability  to  the  people. 
The  formal  machinery  is  not  as  important  as  the  fact  that  the  chief  executive 
is  held  responsible  by  the  public  for  the  whole  program  of  the  government. 
His  direct  responsibility  to  the  people  is  strong  in  the  American  democratic 
tradition.  Let  us  remember  that  the  Electoral  College  was  reduced  to  a  fic- 
tion soon  after  it  had  been  established,  and  that  in  many  a  city  the  voters 
have  chosen  council  members  for  their  support  of  the  city  manager  rather 
than  for  their  own  views  or  personalities. 

The  chief  executive  is  most  effective  in  contributing  to  the  democratic 
workings  of  administration  if  he  combines  with  his  machinery  of  coordi- 
nation a  policy  or  a  philosophy  that  will  stir  the  interest  and  inspire  the 
support  of  his  departments,  the  legislative  body,  and  the  general  public  alike. 
Without  such  a  common  purpose,  the  cooperation  of  free  institutions  is 
transformed  into  the  selfish  defense  of  vested  interests.  With  it,  such  cooper- 
ation multiplies  the  effectiveness  of  governmental  administration,  adding  to 
the  efforts  of  each  single  public  agency  the  energies  that  are  developed  in  the 
varied  organisms  of  a  free  people. 

5.  DEPARTMENTAL  DEMOCRACY 

Individual  Freedom  Versus  Institutional  Restraint.  If  the  purpose  of 
democracy  is  to  make  government  serve  the  highest  ends  of  man,  instead 
of  making  man  serve  the  lowest  ends  of  government,  we  cannot  be  sure 
that  public  administration  will  remain  democratic  in  the  long  run  simply 
by  achieving  satisfactory  working  relations  between  governmental  agencies, 
the  legislature,  and  the  general  public.  We  must  consider  the  way  these 
agencies  are  organized  and  operated,  for  it  is  always  possible  for  an  organi- 
zation to  defeat  its  own  ends  by  becoming  an  end  in  itself. 


92  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

Within  an  organization,  democracy  is  by  no  means  the  same  thing  as 
lack  of  discipline  or  authority.  An  army,  for  example,  can  be  quite  demo- 
cratic even  though  an  officer  has  authority  to  order  his  men  to  certain  death. 
The  question  is  whether  the  administrative  organization  permits  its  mem- 
bers to  retain  their  independence  as  citizens  in  matters  that  do  not  concern 
their  official  duties,  and  whether  it  gives  them  a  chance,  in  performing 
those  duties,  to  make  full  use  of  their  talents  to  further  the  general  welfare. 

Public  officials  and  employees  do  not  need  to  surrender  their  personal 
rights  or  liberties  as  citizens.  Perhaps  the  low  point  of  public  confidence  in 
government,  at  least  in  the  English-language  tradition,  was  reached  for  a 
few  years  in  the  late  eighteenth  century  when  the  British  Parliament  denied 
civil  servants  the  right  to  vote.  That  limitation  was  soon  removed,  but  Great 
Britain  continued  to  restrict  the  political  activities  of  civil  servants  more 
severely  than  did  the  United  States.  America  made  the  opposite  error  of 
letting  political  parties  use  government  employees  for  their  own  purposes, 
until  civil  service  rules  established  the  proposition  that  a  public  servant 
must  not  campaign  in  electoral  contests  for  or  against  the  chief  executive 
or  members  of  the  legislature. 

It  would  probably  be  an  error  for  this  nation  to  adopt,  after  the  British 
fashion,  the  general  principle  that  civil  servants  may  not  take  part  in  or- 
ganizing the  promotion  of  public  policy.  There  are  features  of  the  British 
Constitution  that  justified  that  principle,  and  may  still  justify  it.  The  per- 
manent tenure  of  the  civil  servant,  and  the  possibility  of  change  at  any  time 
in  the  political  direction  of  public  administration,  might  make  it  inconvenient 
to  permit  him  to  take  a  public  stand  on  an  issue  between  his  present 
superiors  and  their  rivals  who  could  become  his  superiors  tomorrow.  Even  so, 
it  is  a  little  hard  to  see  why  it  is  proper  for  civil  servants  to  organize  to  get 
their  salaries  raised  and  improper  for  them  to  take  part  in  more  inclusive 
organizations  in  support  of  other  policies. 

At  one  extreme  there  must  obviously  be  some  limitation;  at  the 
other  extreme  there  need  be  none.  An  officer  in  a  high  position  should  not 
publicly  oppose  his  political  superior's  policy  without  resigning;  and  if  he 
does  oppose  it  in  public,  he  should  be  discharged.  At  the  other  extreme, 
an  employee  with  duties  totally  unrelated  to  policy  ought  to  be— and  gen- 
erally is — permitted  to  take  any  stand  he  likes  on  issues  of  policy. 

The  most  difficult  problems  arise  between  these  two  extremes.  An  offi- 
cial with  a  long-range  interest  in  the  public  service  will  often  find  com- 
promise necessary.  As  long  as  he  is  conscious  of  working  toward  his  general 
objective  as  a  servant  of  the  public,  compromise  is  simply  a  function  of  his 
position.  Government,  of  course,  needs  men  whose  primary  interest  and 
competence  are  focused  in  the  administrative  process  itself,  and  who  can 
help  conduct  administrative  affairs  regardless  of  chanees  in  polirv.  How- 
ever, in  a  dynamic  democracy  there  is  also  room  for  men  who,  while 
not  active  in  electoral  campaigns  or  party  organizations,  are  primarily  inter- 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  93 

csted  in  policies  and  programs,  and  are  quite  willing  to  work  for  these 
either  inside  or  outside  the  government. 

Now  that  the  number  of  civil  servants  is  so  great,  it  is  especially  impor- 
tant to  safeguard  their  political  rights.  As  long  as  we  keep  our  system  of 
cooperative  government,  we  will  never  be  threatened  by  a  gigantic  bu- 
reaucracy all  of  whose  members  vote  for  its  boss.  The  cooperation  of  state 
and  local  governments  and  private  institutions  in  national  administration 
helps  guarantee  the  freedom  and  diversity  of  political  views,  just  as  it 
keeps  our  citizens  from  being  divided  sharply  into  two  parties,  each  differ- 
ing from  the  other  in  political  philosophy  and  in  attitudes  on  all  major 
issues. 

Sense  of  General  Purpose.  At  the  same  time,  administrators  themselves 
ought  to  be  concerned  with  the  political  implications  of  their  own  depart- 
ments and  the  departmental  working  processes.  The  purpose  of  every 
organization  is  partially  defeated  whenever  it  tends  to  become  absorbed  in 
itself  and  in  the  interests  of  its  personnel,  rather  than  in  the  accomplish- 
ment of  its  general  objectives.  The  administrator  ought  not  to  be  blind  to  the 
dangers  of  such  introversion,  for  it  is  a  fault  from  which  none  of  his  man- 
agement formulas  can  save  him. 

There  is,  first  of  all,  one  obvious  danger.  Any  person  may  easily  slide 
into  the  error  of  believing  that  his  organization  exists  primarily  for  him 
and  for  his  particular  category  of  associates.  This  is  a  matter  of  degree. 
In  general,  the  more  the  civic  status  of  public  employees  is  preserved, 
the  less  incentive  they  have  for  considering  their  pay  and  working  condi- 
tions their  prime  objectives.  It  is  quite  proper  to  demand  the  protection 
of  employee  rights  and  to  organize  to  that  end.  It  is  also  quite  proper  to 
take  an  interest  in  the  development  of  a  career  service,  based  on  adequate 
personal  incentives.  At  the  same  time,  neither  the  citizen  nor  the  civil 
servant  ought  to  confuse  the  security  or  conditions  of  government  employ- 
ment with  the  essential  purposes  of  public  administration. 

The  distinction  is  not  always  simple,  but  there  are  several  approaches 
which  will  help  an  agency  head  to  make  it  clearer.  One  is  to  see  that  em- 
ployees have  full  opportunity  to  use  their  abilities  in  the  most  effective  ways. 
No  single  organization  can  do  so  completely,  for  the  purpose  of  the  organi- 
zation itself  is  a  limitation.  A  welfare  agency,  for  example,  could  hardlv 
make  the  best  use  of  a  promising  physicist.  Within  reasonable  limits,  how- 
ever, intelligent  methods  of  recruiting  and  classifying  employees  and  of 
assigning  them  work  that  will  suit  and  develop  their  talents  are  apt  to 
further  at  once  the  efficiency  and  the  democracy  of  administration.  Large 
organizations  can  do  even  more  by  adopting  programs  of  in-service  training 
to  encourage  the  fullest  growth  and  use  of  all  potential  abilities.  Nothing 
weakens  an  administrative  organization  or  a  government  as  a  whole  more 
seriously  than  artificial  barriers  to  the  advancement  of  men  and  women 
with  capacity  and  leadership.  The  traditional  practice  of  American  civil 


94  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

service  commissions  of  considering  only  the  immediate  usefulness  of  a 
recruit,  and  making  little  or  no  effort  to  discover  and  develop  general  admin- 
istrative ability  at  an  early  stage,  cannot  be  justified  on  grounds  of  democ- 
racy; it  is  merely  shortsighted.  It  is  possible  to  develop  administrators  with- 
out having  an  exclusive  and  undemocratic  administrative  class.17 

In  encouraging  employees  to  put  forth  their  best  efforts,  a  great  deal 
depends  on  indefinable  matters  of  personality  and  atmosphere.  It  may  not 
be  too  fanciful  to  suggest,  however,  that  the  qualities  which  enable  a  citi- 
zen to  assert  his  political  independence  while  respecting  the  opinions  and 
personalities  of  others  are  similar  to  those  which  aid  the  administrator  to 
bring  out  the  best  efforts  of  his  subordinates.  The  dictatorial  administrator 
who  makes  personal  issues  out  of  differences  of  judgment  is  likely  to  stifle 
the  advice  on  which  he  must  rely  for  guidance.  On  the  other  hand,  one 
unduly  preoccupied  with  the  personalities  of  his  subordinates — one  who 
fails  to  bring  to  their  attention  the  points  on  which  they  fall  below  his  stand- 
ards, and  who  juggles  his  organization  to  suit  their  peculiarities — may 
merely  find  the  more  scrupulous  to  be  confused  and  uncertain,  and  the 
less  scrupulous  to  be  either  scheming  for  their  own  purposes  or  challenging 
his  leadership.  A  good  measure  of  intelligent  extroversion,  combined  with 
a  sensitivity  for  the  rights  and  feelings  of  others,  will  help  the  administrator 
to  keep  his  agency's  attention  on  the  job  to  be  done  rather  than  on  its 
internal  problems. 

Vice  of  Departmentalism.  A  second  danger  is  the  assumption  that  the 
organization  exists  for  its  own  sake.  The  logical  transition  here  is  easy: 
esprit  de  corps  makes  for  effective  work,  and  esprit  de  corps  is  furthered 
by  expansion  of  the  functions  or  jurisdiction  of  the  organization.  In  mild 
doses  this  is  good  medicine,  but  as  a  steady  diet  it  is  politically  fatal.  Undue 
concentration  of  loyalty  in  the  agency  is  somewhat  akin  to  the  specialist's 
devotion  to  his  own  specialty.  The  formula  of  having  the  expert  "on  tap 
but  not  on  top"  is  easier  to  quote  than  to  apply  in  practice. 

Several  cures  have  been  tried  for  this  ailment.  One  is  to  introduce 
countcrinfluences  in  the  form  of  government-wide  concerns — agencies  to 
aid  the  chief  executive  in  his  widely  embracing  managerial  duties,  such  as 
a  planning  office  or  a  budget  bureau,  or  special  coordinating  machinery. 
Another  is  to  give  multiple  functions  to  a  single  agency  or  a  single  unit 
of  government.  On  this  principle  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  was 
created;  much  earlier  the  entire  system  of  British  local  government  was 
reorganized  on  the  same  principle  to  substitute  a  single  unit  of  government 
in  each  area  for  a  number  of  specialized  authorities.  Still  another  cure  is 
the  systematic  promotion  or  transfer  of  administrative  personnel  from  one 
department  to  another.  The  British  civil  service  adopted  this  idea  for  the 
higher  levels  of  the  administrative  class  more  than  two  decades  ago.  Such 

17  Cf.  above  Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  3,  "Training  for  Public 
Administration.*' 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  95 

transfers  have  probably  done  much  to  make  civil  servants  think  more  of 
the  general  welfare  and  less  of  jurisdictional  disputes. 

If  transfers  of  this  kind  are  good  between  departments,  why  not  apply 
them  between  the  various  levels  of  government  and  between  government 
and  private  institutions?  Government  is  only  one  department  in  the  whole 
organization  of  society,  and  the  changes  in  its  functions  during  the  past 
century  have  made  the  line  between  it  and  private  activities  far  less  sharp. 
Today,  the  top  governmental  administrator  cannot  adequately  judge  his 
agency's  operations  merely  by  the  conventional  standards  of  management; 
he  must  consider  its  effects  on  society  as  a  whole.  To  give  him  the  necessary 
breadth  of  view,  we  may  need  a  wider  interchange  of  top  personnel  among 
levels  of  government  and  between  public  and  private  life.  The  specialists 
in  techniques  and  in  various  subject-matter  fields  are  necessary,  and  will 
want  to  make  life  careers  of  their  work.  However,  they  are  not  likely  to 
develop  the  breadth  of  sympathy  and  imagination  that  an  administrator 
of  the  highest  level  must  have  if  he  is  to  do  his  job  in  the  development  as 
well  as  in  the  execution  of  policy. 

The  spoils  system  was  little  better  than  looting  the  public  treasury.  But 
the  theory  of  rotation  in  office  is  not  the  same  as  that  of  partisan  spoils.  In 
a  general  sense  it  has  always  applied  in  American  life,  private  as  well  as 
public.  Visitors  from  more  static  or  more  stable  societies  invariably  wonder 
at  the  American's  tendency  to  change  from  job  to  job,  or  to  occupy  several 
jobs  at  once.  Perhaps  we  should  rediscover  or  bring  up  to  date  the  theory 
that  Jefferson  and  Jackson  held  about  public  office.  It  is  not  that  public  ad- 
ministration is  so  simple  a  matter  that  anyone  can  master  it  in  a  short  time. 
On  the  contrary,  it  is  so  complex  that  few  can  comprehend  the  problems 
that  arise  at  its  higher  levels  without  having  had  wider  experience,  and 
not  in  government  alone.18 

Inroads  of  Perfectionism.  A  third  trap  awaits  the  administrator  who 
seeks  to  do  the  job  assigned  to  him  by  law  and  executive  direction.  It  is 
the  danger  that  the  administrative  process  will  become  an  object  in  itself, 
that  the  very  art  of  generalization  will  be  converted  into  a  specialty.  Some 
managers  allow  their  personal  analytical  and  critical  processes  to  absorb  their 
attention.  As  a  result,  they  fail  to  let  subordinates  do  their  jobs  in  their 
own  ways,  thus  obstructing  the  development  of  diverse  abilities  and  the 
release  of  individual  energies  throughout  the  organization.  Others  become 
hypnotized  by  the  procedures  of  management.  A  manual  of  procedures  has 
its  uses,  but  like  other  written  rules  it  is  apt  to  turn  sterile  unless  it  is  the 
elaboration  of  a  common  will,  a  real  agreement  of  minds  within  the  or^ani- 
zation  on  objectives  and  on  the  type  of  teamwork  by  which  they  are  to  be 
effected. 


is  Of  course,  this  proposition  is  quite  different  from  the  historic  use*  of  rotation  in  office 
for  patronage  purposes;  cf.  above  Ch.  1,  "The  Growth  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  4,  "In- 
creasing Competence  for  Increasing  Responsibility." 


96  DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION 

Delegation  depends  on  the  assumption  that  some  other  man  can  do  the 
job  as  well  as  the  delegating  superior,  once  the  proper  general  directions 
are  established.  The  popular  axiom,  "If  you  want  a  job  well  done,  do  it 
yourself,"  is  the  opposite  cf  administration.  Yet  a  kind  of  perfectionism 
sometimes  creeps  into  management.  It  is  shown  by  a  preference  for  making 
all  decisions  at  headquarters  rather  than  leaving  some  of  them  to  the  field; 
headquarters  will  make  no  mistakes,  even  if  a  bottleneck  develops.  It  is 
shown  by  a  preference  for  flooding  the  field  with  detailed  instructions;  it  is 
best  to  make  sure  that  all  is  settled  in  terms  of  the  letter  of  the  directives. 
It  is  shown  by  a  preference  for  centralized  national  administration  in  all 
circumstances;  it  is  better  to  have  a  uniform  policy  and  no  local  variations, 
even  if  the  program  fails  to  win  general  understanding  and  acceptance. 

Yet  these  perfectionist  assumptions  usually  break  down  because  the  very 
nature  of  public  affairs  requires  their  administration  with  flexibility  and 
initiative  on  lower  levels.  It  is,  therefore,  just  as  desirable  to  get  the  views 
of  the  men  in  the  field  as  the  views  of  the  department  head.  In  a  quite  literal 
sense,  headquarters  must  serve  the  field  officers  and  the  field  officers  must 
serve  the  public  if  the  organization  is  to  be  democratically  efficient  in  its 
administration. 

Democratic  Self -Education.  The  purposes  of  democratic  society  deserve 
the  best  administration  that  can  be  had.  No  less  will  do  the  job.  And  the 
administrator  who  today  is  doing  his  best  hardly  need  worry  about  the  stale 
charges  of  czarism  and  dictatorship  that  are  now  being  taken  up  by  scholars, 
after  decades  of  careless  use  by  political  hacks.  On  the  contrary,  he  should 
be  heartened  by  the  way  in  which  the  administrative  process  has  broadened 
and  become  more  democratic  during  the  past  generation,  even  during  the 
war  years  when  concentration  of  authority  might  have  provided  an  excuse 
for  more  authoritarian  policies. 

This  broadening  of  participation  in  our  national  administration  must  not 
be  credited  to  any  single  group  or  party.  It  is  the  result  of  a  gradual 
strengthening  of  local  and  group  responsibilities  throughout  the  nation,  and 
of  a  freer  exchange  of  ideas  and  personnel  among  all  levels  of  government 
and  private  organizations,  including  business  corporations.  In  its  more 
successful  programs,  contemporary  government  makes  it  plain  to  the  citi- 
zen that  while  the  best  administration  is  certainly  democratic,  the  most 
democratic  administration  is  also  the  most  efficient. 

In  order  to  provide  a  cohesive  force  for  this  cooperative  system,  we 
should  encourage  among  our  administrative  officials  active  and  responsible 
participation  in  the  development  of  policy.19  The  old  proposition  that  policy 


19  To  be  sure,  no  one  would  want  to  minimize  the  basic  distinction  between  responsible 
and  irresponsible  participation  in  policy  development.  Some  of  the  standards  of  responsibility 
in  this  sphere  have  been  outlined  in  the  present  chapter.  Others  are  suggested  above  in  Ch.  1, 
"The  Growth  of  Public  Administration,"  sec  1,  "Administration — Public  and  Private,"  and 
Ch.  3,  "Bureaucracy — Fact  and  Fiction,"  sec.  1.  "Semantics  and  Realities." 


DEMOCRATIC  ADMINISTRATION  97 

and  administration  are  mutually  exclusive  spheres  of  activity  never  fully 
applied  anywhere.  Particularly,  it  never  fitted  the  United  States.  And 
today,  when  the  political  fate  of  the  world  depends  on  our  ability  to  coordi- 
nate technologies  while  encouraging  initiative,  it  is  necessary  for  administra- 
tive officials  to  help  in  the  charting  of  our  social  policies,  even  though  they 
must  remain  fully  responsible  to  legislative  control  and  to  direction  by 
democratically  chosen  executives. 

The  dynamics  of  our  democracy  cannot  be  a  simple  process  of  right 
pulling  against  left;  it  must  rather  be  a  process  of  organizing  both  public 
opinion  to  support  a  policy  and  machinery  to  carry  it  out.  Our  social  fron- 
tiers will  move  forward  not  according  to  abstract  theories  but  as  fast  as  we 
can  educate  one  another  to  the  possibility  of  effective  cooperation.  This 
process  of  democratic  self-education  is  one  of  the  main  aspects  of  public 
administration.  To  it  the  administrative  official  must  contribute  his  full 
share. 


CHAPTER 


The  Social  Function  of  Public  Administration 

1.  THE  "AMERICAN  SYSTEM"  AND  THE  SERVICE  STATE 

Wartime  Record.  In  their  official  report  on  war  and  postwar  adjustment 
policy  released  early  in  1944,  Bernard  Baruch  and  John  Hancock  cast  an 
appraising  glance  at  "all  of  the  economic  systems  of  the  world"  and  con- 
cluded that  "the  American  system  has  outproduced  the  world."  But  they 
added  a  very  significant  qualification  on  the  manner  in  which  this  "miracle" 
— as  they  put  it — had  been  achieved.  "With  the  coming  of  wqu\"  they 
observed,  va  sort  of  totalitarianism  is  asserted  .  .  .  planning  and  execution 
rest  upon  one  over-all  purpose  and  a  single  control."])  This  tribute  to  both 
the  power  of  our  common  determination  and  the  role  of  government  in 
directing  the  mobilization  of  our  resources  as  a  nation  appears  to  suggest 
a  lesson  for  peace  as  well  as  war. 

War  is  not  the  only  teacher  of  patriotism  and  civic  solidarity.  True 
dedication  of  our  individual  efforts  to  the  organic  development  of  demo- 
cratic society  might  furnish  us  on  a  national  scale  with  the  "moral  equiva- 
lent of  war,"  to  use  William  James'  phrase.2  If  we  can  attain  greater  service 
from  our  economy  by  effective  cooperation  under  the  auspices  of  "one  over- 
all purpose  and  a  single  control,"  should  we  not  hasten  to  seek  the  better  life 
by  adopting  for  peacetime  use  the  wartime  features  of  the  "American  sys- 
tem" which  proved  the  key  to  victory? 

Peacetime  Relevance  of  Wartime  Achievement.  An  affirmative  answer 
could  find  support  in  the  character  of  our  wartime  experience,  we  reached 
not  only  unprecedented  levels  of  productivity  and  national  income  but  also 
a  high  mark  of  direct  citizen  participation  in  governmental  activities  such 
as  selective  service  administration,  civilian  defense,  and  price  and  rationing 
administration!)  Our  democratic  structure  of  government  remained  intact, 

.     *  Senate  Doc.  No.  154,  78th  Cong.,  2d  Sess.,  pp.  3,  7,  Washington:   Government  Printing 
Office,  1944. 

2  James*  great  essay  under  this  tide  has  been  reprinted  in  Winslow,  Thacher  and  t)avidson, 
Frank  P.,  eds.,  American  Youth,  p.  181  ff.,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1940. 

98 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  99 

and  our  fundamental  liberties  were  not  undermined.  In  the  spherc^pf  busi- 
ness, the  "American  system"  retained  its  identity  as  an  enterprise  economy, 
in  the  main  individually  owned  and  managed  for  private  gain.  By  har- 
nessing  our  full  productive  strength,  we  succeeded  in  building  a  vast  war 
economy  atop  our  peace  economy.  At  no  time  in  our  history  had  we  accom- 
plished anything  like  it. 

Yet  we  are  far  from  assuming  that  the  scheme  which  served  us  well  in 
war  would  provide  us  with  a  sound  working  formula  for  peacetime  living. 
Winning  a  war  is  a  goal  for  which  we  close  ranks  almost  automatically. 
Safeguarding  prosperity  in  the  context  of  the  democratic  way  of  life  is  an 
equally  worthy  end,  but  one  for  which  we  have  not  yet  evolved  a  generally 
acceptable  organizational  pattern.  To  very  articulate  groups,  in  fact,  the  es- 
sence of  the  "American  system"  lies  precisely  in  the  absence  of  any  "single 
control,"  any  "regimentation,"  any  "sort  of  totalitarianism."  Spokesmen  of 
these  groups  have  always  insisted  that  the  "American  system"  itself  demands 
that  government  "stay  out  of  business"  and  leave  the  economy  to  its 
"natural  laws."  "  ~~~ 

Long-Range  Trend  Toward  the  Service  State.  However  vigorously  this 
doctrine  has  been  expounded,  it  is  clear  that  we  have  never  attempted  to 
practice  it  consistently.  Suffice  it  to  mention  the  Articles  of  Confederation, 
formulated  in  1777,  which  authorized  government  to  "go  into  business"  by 
establishing  its  "sole  and  exclusive  right  and  power"  to  run  the  postal  serv- 
ice. Indeed,  (.next  to  our  unparalleled  technological  advance,  perhaps  the 
most  striking  thing  about  the  "American  system"  in  the  historic  perspective 
is  the  steady  growth  of  direct  andJndi/^i4UibUc^orUrols---by  regulation,, 
by  taxation,  by^enfi^^TTT^ageina^nt  and  use  of j^neyjinSarecTiffty En- 
forcement of  standards  of  safety,  by  governmental  insurance  of  risks,  by  pre- 
serving industrial  peace,  by  social  rehabilitation,  by  providing  a  host  of 
specialized  services  to  meet  particular  group  needs.)  For  better  or  for  worse, 
all  of  this  is  part  of  the  "American  system." 

Nor  can  it  be  argued  that  the  gradual  emergence  of  such  public  controls 
arose  from  conspirational  scheming  or  lust  for  power,  or  zest  for  interfer- 
ence on  the  part  of  government.  Traditionally  suspicious  of  authority,  we 
resorted  to  new  controls  only  in  the  face  of  strong  popular  pressures  or  con- 
ditions that  cried  out  for  remedy.  On  this  score,  there  is  no  real  difference 
in  the  records  of  the  Republican  and  Democratic  parties.  In  each  instance, 
governmental  action,  preventive  or  curative,  presented  itself  as  the  lesser 
evil,  when  compared  with  an  unmeliorated  status  quo.  Sometimes  the  action 
taken  was  futile;  sometimes  it  was  foolish.  Sometimes  it  was  clumsily  de- 
vised and  incompetently  executed.  Even  if  it  met  our  expectations,  our 
satisfaction  was  not  unmixed.  After  all,  is  not  the  lesser  evil  still  an  evil? 

One  important  fact,  however,  stood  out.  As  the  framework  of  public 
concern  and  superintendence  widened,  we  managed  to  narrow  the  Dan- 
gerous chasm  between  wealth  and  poverty,  increase  our  economic  health, 


100  THE   SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

and  raise  the  national  standard  of  living.  Government,  by  expanding  its 
functions  in  the  social  and  economic  realms,  simultaneously  broadened  the 
meaning  of  democracy)  This  was  the  "trend  toward  the  service  state"  which 
Leonard  D.  White  had  found  in  evidence  in  the  administrative  evolution  of 
the  first  three  decades  of  the  twentieth  century.3  It  is  still  going  strong. 

Assurance  Versus  Fear.  Up  to  the  day  of  Pearl  Harbor,  the  implications 
of  this  trend  were  by  no  means  universally  appreciated.  Like  parents  who 
do  not  see  their  children  grow,  most  of  us  would  not  have  known  a  trend 
had  we  met  one.  Those  who  became  aware  of  it  were  more  inclined  to 
decry  it  than  to  weigh  its  deeper  consequences.  Time  and  again  —  and  with 
increasing  frequency  during  the  past  generation  —  we  had  been  chilled  by 
prophecies  of  impending  doom.  How  could  free  enterprise  or,  for  that  mat- 
ter, any  freedom  survive  if  government  continued  to  reach  out  farther  and 
farther?  How  could  our  economic  efficiency  —  the  very  basis  of  our  existence 
—  hold  up  if  government  meddling  drained  all  initiative  from  private  man- 
agement? Questions  such  as  these  inspired  gloom  rather  than  assurance. 
However,  while  we  tended  to  default  on  convincing  answers,  the  trend  went 
on.  Political  power  changed  hands,  but  no  party  clothed  with  governmental 
responsibility  found  it  practical  to  call  a  halt  and  defy  the  "trend  toward  the 
service  state."  Is  it  reasonable  to  assume  that  we  simply  did  not  know  what 
we  were  doing  ? 

It  is  much  easier  to  accept  the  propositions  that  the^  service  state  isjlem- 
ocracjr  broughtjipdLD-date;  that  the  extension  of  direct  and  indirect  public 
controls  aims  at  the  assertion  of  democracy  in  the  nerve  centers  of  modern 
industrial  society;  and  that  modern  industrial  society  can  endure  in  rela- 
tive freedom  only  through  such  assertion.  This  is  not  a  new  or  abrupt 
turn.  It  is  our  chief  means  of  preserving  our  political  heritage.  As  one  of 
the  ablest  defenders  of  the  "middle  way"  expressed  it  more  than  ten  years 
ago,  "The  liberty  which  our  Anglo-Saxon  ancestors  have  fought  to  maintain 
for  fifty  generations  has  been  liberty  underjaw.,  aru|  Inw  means  regulation."1 
Liberty  under  law  is  at  the  same  time  liberty  bolstered  by  law,  enriched  and 
amplified  by  law  —  liberty  not  only  for  the  economically  strong  but  also  for 
the  economically  weaET^ln  thiiT  sense,  the  service  state  is  the  charter  of  free- 
dom for  the  commonjrian.  Here  Jefferson's  faith  in  the  rank  and  file  and 
Hamilton's  vision"  of  active  government  promoting  the  public^  intcrestjink 
up  with  each  other  in  ~ 


Test  of  the  Service  State.  World  War  II  was  an  undoubted  test  of  the 
"American  system."  It  was  also  a  test  of  the  service  state.  In  terms  of  exist- 
ing governmental  machinery,  we  were  far  better  equipped  at  its  outset  than 

3  Trends  in  Public  Administration,  p.  341,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1933. 

4  John  Dickinson,  in  presenting  the  government  side  on  the  constitutionality  of  the  Bitu- 
minous Coal   Conservation  Act  of   1935,  Senate  Doc.  No.   197,  74th  Cong.,  2d  Sess.,  p.   15, 
Washington:    Government  Printing  Office,  1936.    Dickinson's  general  position  is  concisely  out- 
lined in  his  Hold  Fast  the  Middle  Way,  Boston:    Little,  Brown  &  Co.,  1935.   This  book  has 
hardlv  found  the  attention  it  deserves. 


THE   SOCIAL   FUNCTION   OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  101 

we  had  been  as  we  stood  on  the  threshhold  of  World  War  I.  Starting  with 
that  federal  machinery,  we  proceeded  to  strengthen  it  by  putting  ourselves, 
for  the  duration  of  the  national  emergency,  under  "a  sort  of  totalitarianism." 
Thus  forearmed,  with  all  of  our  great  resources  at  the  nation's  command, 
we  set  a  world  record  of  production.  Could  we  have  forged  ahead  as  we 
did  had  we  left  private  enterprise  to  its  own  planning  and  aspirations?  The 
question  is  purly  rhetorical.  The  triumph  of  the  "American  system"  was  a 
triumph  of  creative  enterprise  backed  by  the  service  state. 

But  a  real  issue  remains.  Obviously,  no  one  would  contend  that  what 
democracy  needs  is  "a  sort  of  totalitarianism."  Wartime  demands  are  extraor- 
dinary. Nations  cannot  afford  to  be  slow  in  getting  into  their  stride.  We 
confront  an  entirely  different  situation  in  peacetime.  Again  we  shall  be 
more  circumspect  and  hesitant  about  means  even  when  we  agree  on  ulti- 
mate ends.  Again  we  shall  bicker  and  quarrel  among  ourselves  for  selfish 
reasons.  Again  we  shall  sneer  at  authority  for  the  fun  of  it.  And  authority, 
in  turn,  will  no  longer  be  supported  by  those  standards  of  exceptional  lati- 
tude which  are  the  essence  of  war  powers  under  the  Constitution.  Granted 
all  of  this,  we  shall  nevertheless  have  to  organize  ourselves  in  order  to  ensure 
our  well-being  as  a  nation. 

2.  THE  NEEDS  OF  THE  SERVICE  STATE 

Making  Democracy  Succeed.  Viewed  against  peacetime's  much-increased 
opportunities  for  disruptive  disagreement,  our  postwar  assignment  as  a  na- 
tion, at  home  and  abroad,  looks  formidable,  to  say  the  least.  Internationally, 
enduring  peace  itself  may  be  lost  unless  we  fully  act  out  our  role  as  a  senior 
partner  of  potentially  decisive  influence  in  shaping  a  world  organization 
that  will  marshal  both  strength  and  wisdom.  In  the  domestic  sphere,  we 
are  virtually  committed  to  perpetuation  of  the  wartime  "miracle"  of  pro- 
ductive abundance  and  maximum  employment.  This  is  not  just  a  bois- 
terous roar  of  self-confidence.  It  is  a  matter  of  necessity. 

All  of  us  know  that  democracy  victorious  in  battle  cannot  convert  itself 
into  democracy  choked  by  unemployment  without  simultaneously  forfeiting 
its  future.  Therefore,  America  as  well  as  Great  Britain  may  well  ponder 
the  significance  of  Lord  Woolton's  famous  White  Paper  on  Employment 
Policy — issued  before  the  climax  of  the  war — which  bluntly  declared  in  its 
first  sentence,  vThe  Government  accept  as  one  of  their  primary  aims  and 
responsibilities  the  maintenance  of  a  high  and  stable  level  of  employment 
after  the  war.*)  If  we  had  not  already  gone  some  distance  in  the  direction 
of  the  service  state,  we  would  have  to  start  now  in  a  hurry.  For  it  is  plain 
that  the  discharge  of  any  such  broad  governmental  responsibility,  involving 
as  it  does  the  corollary  of  "taking  action  at  the  earliest  possible  stage  to 
arrest  a  threatened  slump,"  entails  a  "new  approach"5  and  specific  machinery 
for  its  application. 

5Cd.  6527,  pp.  3,  16,  London:  His  Majesty's  Stationery  Office,  1944. 


102  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

This  machinery  must  be  both  highly  sensitive  and  of  great  dependability, 
even  though  most  of  it  may  not  be  in  the  nature  of  an  expansion  of  regu- 
latory power  in  the  usual  sense.  Proper  reliance  on  devices  other  than 
regulatory  ones  is  a  traditional  aspect  of  the  service  state.  Fiscal  policy 
is  a  goodjllustration.  (As  World  War  II  taught  us  how  to  direct  our  enter- 
prise economy  for  national  purposes,  so  we  learned  in  the  stress  and  strain  of 
economic  mobilization  the  real  significance  of  fiscal  policy  in  its  several 
components — expenditures,  taxes,  borrowing,  and  management  of  the  public 
debt.  In  the  postwar  period,  fiscal  policy  is  likely  to  emerge  as  one  of 
government's  main  tools  for  achieving  a  satisfactory  level  of  employment. 

Through  fiscal  policy  we  can  most  effectively  influence  the  volume  and 
direction  of  spending,  the  rate  and  character  of  investment,  the  course  of 
inflationary  or  deflationary  developments — a  wide  range  of  factors  that  enter 
into  the  business  cycled  However,  determinations  in  the  field  of  fiscal  policy 
must  rest  on  a  large  body  of  factual  knowledge  as  well  as  sound  theory. 
Each  determination,  moreover,  requires  some  implementation  through 
appropriate  administrative  mechanisms.  Even  indirect  controls  such  as 
those  of  fiscal  policy  depend  for  their  success  on  adequately  staffed  statis- 
tical and  research  services,  and  a  variety  of  regulatory  facilities  which  ^n 
be  brought  to  bear  on  policy  execution.  Of  course,  when  government™ 
effect  assumes  responsibility  for  underwriting  prosperity,  it  must  be  fully 
equipped  for  the  task.  We  would  not  choose  a  dentist  who  prides  himself 
on  doing  everything  with  a  single  instrument. 

Continuity  of  Progress.  It  is  certainly  a  great  advantage  that  in  setting 
our  sights  for  the  postwar  period  we  are  not  embarking  upon  a  wholly 
novel  venture.  We  may  have  to  improvise  and  experiment,  but  for  the 
most  part  such  improvisation  and  experimentation  will  be  guided  by  prac- 
tical experience  gained  in  the  past.  Hence,  the  "trend  toward  the  service 
state"  is  in  itself  a  valuable  legacy.  Fortunately,  it  is  a  legacy  which  bears 
the  imprint  of  times  of  peace,  and  for  this  reason  lends  itself  better  to  peace- 
time application  than  would  any  innovations  springing  from  wartime  neces- 
sities. If  we  had  only  the  wartime  record  to  guide  us,  we  might  be  very 
doubtful  about  its  longer-range  relevance.  The  American  people  have  more 
than  once  startled  their  enemies  by  throwing  all  of  their  might  into  un- 
wanted war.  Yet  they  have  always  drawn  a  sharp  line  between  waging 
war  with  all  their  power  and  returning  to  their  peacetime  business.  If  they 
have  erred  in  this  respect  at  all,  the  error  has  been  on  the  side  of  being 
too  rigid  in  observing  the  necessary  line  of  demarcation. 

Small  wonder  that  the  service  state,  in  recapturing  for  democracy  and 
for  accountability  to  the  public  some  vital  areas  of  social  and  economic 
life,  has  met  stubborn  resistance  by  those  who  had  previously  staked  claims 
to  immunity  and  exemption  for  their  own  ends.  Laissez  faire  had  its  en- 
chantment for  the  few  when  the  many  did  not  stir.  But  even  in  its  heyday 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  103 

the  doctrine  of  government  nonintervention  was  elastic  enough  to  allow 
for  tariff  protection  by  government.  And  the  idea  of  protection  carried  over 
into  other  fields.  Industrial  society  cannot  endure  without  a  considerable 
degree  of  stability,  firmly  grounded  in  law  and  regulation. 

As  we  plunged  repeatedly  from  heights  of  prosperity  into  valleys  of 
depression,  we  learned  to  fashion  ^safeguards  against  recurrent  calamities. 
Eventually,  these  safeguards  extended  all  the  way  from  government  pro- 
tection against  monopolistic  exploitation  and  cutthroat  .competition  for  the 
sake  of  free  and  fair  competition  to  government  protection  against  the 
hazards  of  old  age  and  unemployment.  Nor  must  we  forget  the  remark- 
able spread  of  government  lending  activities,  which  reached  an  unprece- 
dented expanse  in  the  establishment,  at  the  close  of  the  Hoover  Adminis- 
tration, of  the  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation.  This  agency  alone 
has  probably  done  more  for  business  than  was  accomplished  for  the  unem- 
ployed by  all  the  public  works  programs  of  the  Great  Depression^ 

Surviving  Contradictions.  Have  there  been  planners  of  the  service 
state?  Not  in  the  sense  in  which  we  think  today  of  planning.  The  service 
state  was  not  conceived  on  any  general  plan.  As  we  sought  remedies  against 
economic  and  social  ills  and  ailments  over  more  than  half  a  century,  we  in- 
serted public  controls  in  piecemeal  fashion  and  at  a  variety  of  points.  If  in 
the  end  the  cumulative  effects  of  these  efforts  came  to  resemble  something 
like  a  coherent  scheme,  it  was  by  accident  rather  than  by  prior  intent  or 
design.  However,  by  the  eve  of  World  War  II  the  outlines  of  a  reasonably 
consistent  scheme  had  become  apparent.6 

It  is  true  that  contradictions  in  structure  still  remained  visible,  but  they 
were  negligible  in  comparison  with  the  unresolved  and  more  fundamental 
contradiction  in  public  attitudes  toward  the  service  state.^On  the  one  hand, 
no  open-minded  observer  could  fail  to  notice  that  the  \Ajnerican  system" 
had  long  ceased  to  be  one  of  private  enterprise  exclusively,  that  it  had  be- 
come in  fact  a  mixed  economy  in  which  both  the  private  and  the  public 
sectors  fulfilled  essential  tasks,  in  many  ways  complementary  in  nature. 
It  was  apparent  that  a  decisive  weakening  of  the  public  sector  would  merely' 
restore  earlier  conditions  of  social  and  economic  vulnerability  which  today 
no  other  democratic  nation  in  the  world  is  willing  to  tolerate.  On  the  other 
hand,  all  too  many  of  us  are  still  captives  of  obsolete  slogans  and  stereotypes 
which  depict  the  service  state  as  a  parasite  feasting  on  the  body  of  the 
"American  system."  This  fundamental  contradiction,  more  than  anything 
else,  accounts  for  the  fickle  climate  of  opinion  in  which  the  service  state 
operates.  How  can  we  acquire  the  highest  degree  of -skill  in  operating  the 
governmental  machine  when  we  permit  ourselves  to  be  obsessed  with  the 
idea  that  the  machine  will  destroy  us? 

6  Perhaps  the  best  comprehensive  description  of  the  service  state  before  our  entry  into 
World  War  II  is  contained  in  Lyon,  Lcverett  S.  and  Associates,  Government  and  Economic  Life, 
2  vols.,  Washington:  Brookings  Institution,  1939-1940. 


104  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

It  is  vital  that  we  take  a  calmer  view  of  the  service  state  as  a  set  of  in- 
stitutions that  have  grown  to  be  indispensable  in  sustaining  our  economy. 
The  question  has  never  been  one  of  liquidating  those  institutions  in  the 
interest  of  an  entirely  unworkable,  absolute  freedom  of  enterprise.  Abso- 
lute freedom  would  annul  all  community.  More  than  once  in  the  past, 
we  have  been  reminded  by  the  Supreme  Court  itself  that  the  free  society  en- 
dorsed by  the  Constitution  involves  the  mutual  adjustment  of  rights,  that 
all  rights  are  relative,  and  that  each  right  is  conditional  on  the  self-preser- 
vation of  the  public  order.  The  service  state,  being  merely  a  means  to  an 
end,  effects  such  adjustments  both  in  the  relation  of  right  to  right  and 
in  the  relation  of  right  to  obligation. 

However,  the  service  state  cannot  make  its  full  potential  contribution  if 
its  principal  purpose  is  misunderstood.  It  cannot  do  two  things  at  once — 
attain  its  basic  goal  within  the  framework  of  democracy  and  at  the  same  time 
fight  a  running  battle  in  defense  of  its  existence.  As  long  as  powerful  groups 
and  special  interests  inveigh  against  the  conception  as  well  as  the  machinery 
of  the  service  state,  they  have  no  ground  for  the  complaint  that  government 
offers  no  full  assurance  of  its  competence  to  cope  with  complex  processes. 
For  it  is  precisely  the  perennial  denunciation  of  the  service  state  that  inter- 
feres most  seriously  with  the  gradual  refinement  and  perfection  of  respon- 
sive and  responsible  government. 

Beyond  this  question  of  public  confidence — identical  in  the  main  with 
confidence  in  democracy  and  democratic  procedure-£stress  must  be  laid  on 
other  elementary  needs  of  the  service  state.  Eitst,  there  is  the  need  for  re- 
sourceful public  -management.  Second,  there  are  the  related  needs  for  public 
planning  and  policy  continuity.  Third,  there  is  the  need  for  continuous 
synthesis  of  fundamental  motivations — political,  economic,  and  social.  Each 
of  these  needs  involves  the  interplay  of  all  three  branches  of  government, 
legislative,  executive,  and  judicial.  No  one  branch — and  no  one  level  of 
g(>tfernment — can  singly  undertake  the  whole  assignment.  Willing  coop- 
eration among  all  three  branches  and  on  all  three  levels  is  imperative.  So 
is  civic  cooperation.^) 

As  long  as  its  elementary  needs  are  only  partly  met,  the  service  state 
remains  little  more  than  an  idea.  As  long  as  its  needs  are  answered  only 
in  a  haphazard  way  and  without  sufficient  attention  to  their  interrelations, 
it  will  fail  to  mature.  QThere  is  a  vast  difference  between  maintaining  large- 
scale  governmental  organization,  operating  at  limited  capacity,  and  actually 
securing  the  greatest  benefits  from  that  organization)  If  in  the  machine 
age  it  is  impossible  for  democracy  to  keep  itself  alive  without  the  reenforce- 
ment  which  the  service  state  provides,  it  should  follow  that  we  ought  to 
exert  ourselves  to  make  the  most  of  our  opportunity. 

J  Requirements  of  Public  Management.  This  is  not  the  place  to  unfold 
in  detail  the  major  themes  suggested  in  any  enumeration  of  basic  require- 
ments. That  will  be  done  in  subsequent  chapters.  Here,  passing  reference 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  105 

to  only  the  most  obvious  implications  must  be  sufficient.  Resourceful  man- 
agement in  government  presupposes  several  things.  In  the  first  place,  the 
public  sector  of  the  "American  system"  must  be  nourished  with  adminis- 
trative and  professional  talent  at  least  in  the  same  degree  to  which  that 
talent  has  been  drawn  into  the  private  sector  since  the  advent  of  industriali- 
zation. This  is  not  simply  a  matter  of  appropriate  standards  for  entrance 
into  public  service.  It  also  raises  the  problem  of  making  public  employ- 
ment attractive  in  terms  of  both  general  prestige  and  career  opportunities/ 
And,  sgcondj  we  cannot  delay  for  long  a  practical  reconciliation  of  the 
increasing  demands  for  administrative  self-reliance,  initiative,  and  inventive- 
ness with  more  concise  elaboration  of  effective  forms  of  general  control  and 
administrative  responsibility.  Thus  far,  legislative  control  has  succeeded 
neither  in  securing  true  accountability  nor^in  showing  itself  capable  of 
promoting  vigorous  management.8  On  this  score,  the  record  of  private 
business  is  more  satisfactory  than  that  of  government As  we  know  also 
from  our  experience  with  judicial  control  over  administration,  responsibility 
is  weakened  rather  than  strengthened  if  it  is  exacted  primarily  TnTTegative 

forms  of  invalidation.  • — - 

"Requirements  of  Policy  Planning.  Equally  important  is  the  need  for 
adequate  organization  for  public  planning  and  policy  continuity.  A  people 
united  in  the  pursuit  of  its  main  national  objectives  can  well  be  presumed 
to  give  unified  direction  to  public  undertakings.  When  unity  of  purpose  is 
impaired,  distortion  of  general  policy  through  minority  pressures  and  vested 
interests  is  not  checked  readily.9  However,  the  impact  of  these  forces  of 
distortion  may  be  lessened  in  large  measure  by  governmental  arrangements 
designed  to  bring  forth  something  like  a  rationally  conceived  national 
agenda.  Planning  is  an  inseparable  aspect  of  our  civilization.  It  is  recog- 
nized by  industry  as  a  source  of  profit  and  an  insurance  agaiftst  loss.  We 
cannot  do  without  it  in  carrying  on  our  business  as  a  nation.10  While  today 
this  assertion  is  perhaps  uncontroversial,  it  cannot  be  said  that  we  are  unani- 
mous on  such  questions  as  the  proper  location  of  the  planning  function 
and  the  scope  of  its  mandate.  Acknowledgment  of  the  importance  of  plan- 
ning does  not  carry  with  it  any  commitment  on  the  questionable  alternative 
between  economic  freedom  and  a  planned  society.  The  degree  of  planning, 
realistically  speaking,  will  with  us  always  depend  on  practical  needs,  not 

7  The  outstanding  American  report  in  this  area  is  now  more  than  ten  years  old:    Com- 
mission  of  Inquiry  on   Public   Service  Personnel,   Better  Government  Personnel,  New  York: 
McGraw-Hill,  1935. 

8  Reference  may  here  be  made  ag*»in  tp  one  of  the  most  incisive  public  documents  bearing 
directly  on  this  question:    President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with 
Special  Studies,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937. 

9  A  sharp  picture  of  the  inroads  of  special  interests  into  the  general  welfare  is  presented 
in  Chase,  Stuart,  Democracy  under  Pressure,  New  York:   Twentieth  Century  Fund,  1945. 

10  For  an  authoritative  account  of  a  significant  "chapter  in  American  planning  experience,*' 
see  Merriam,  Charles  E.,  "The  National  Resources  Planning  Board,"  American  Political  Science 
Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1075  ff. 


106  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

on  abstract  preferences  expressed  in  oversimplifications.  Looking  toward 
its  postwar  responsibilities,  government  cannot  be  indifferent  to  the  waste 
and  peril  of  contradictions  in  policy.  Consistency  of  policy,  on  the  other 
hand,  calls  for  combined  legislative  and  administrative  operations. 

We  can  best  hope  to  attain  synthesis  of  fundamental  motivations  on  the 
basis  of  a  national  agenda.  Above  all,  such  an  agenda  would  define  and 
clarify  the  tasks  of  government  in  relation  to  our  economic  and  social  life. 
As  one  result,  the  respective  functions  of  the  private  and  public  sectors  of 
our  mixed  economy  could  be  circumscribed  more  explicitly.  Once  these 
respective  functions  stood  out  in  greater  clarity,  we  could  hope  to  reduce 
substantially  the  dangers  of  friction  and  disruption.  To  the  same  extent 
we  would  win  a  precious  chance  of  increasing  the  general  efficiency  of  the 
"American  system."  If  we  seize  upon  this  chance,  we  are  bound  to  gain 
more  than  mere  material  advantages.  By  developing  our  confidence  in  the 
soundness  of  our  approach  and  in  our  capacity  for  operating  effectively  as 
a  nation,  we  can  make  it  plain  to  everyone — including  ourselves — that 
democracy  is  not  something  nice  to  talk  about  but  that  it  can  work, 

3.  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION — INSTRUMENT  OF  GOVERNMENT 

Prominence  of  Public  Administration.  The  most  distinctive  character- 
istic of  the  service  state  is  the  prominence  of  public  administration.  As 
government  shifts  from  a  relatively  passive  to  an  increasingly  active  role, 
it  inevitably  expands  its  machinery  of  action.  This  machinery  assumes  the 
character  of  a  permanent  establishment  because  government  is  compelled 
to  take  on  continuing  responsibilities  which  can  be  fulfilled  only  through 
continuity  of  operations. 

Typically,  continuing  administrative  operations  fall  within  the  province 
of  the  executive  branch.  Typically  also,  their  conduct  requires  the  dele- 
gation of  administrative  power  to  each  individual  agency.  While  it  is 
true  that  even  the  weakest  administrative  system  must  have  at  its  disposal 
some  degree  of  administrative  power,  in  our  day  such  power  has  acquired 
an  importance  in  the  life  of  the  citizen  equal  to  that  of  legislative  power 
and  in  certain  ways  much  greater  than  that  of  judicial  power.  This  devel- 
opment, being  actually  a  manifestation  of  the  "trend  toward  the  service 
state,"  has  been  in  evidence  as  long  as  the  trend  itself.  Several  years  before 
the  birth  of  the  New  Deal,  Ernst  Freund,  a  leading  authority  on  admin- 
istrative law,  observed  that  ^"administrative  power  appears  as  one  of  the 
established  political  facts  in  present-day  government.^1  His  judgment  was 
not  ahead  of  the  times,  even  though  it  was  not  yet  reflected  in  the  editorial 
pages  of  our  newspapers. 

Demands  on  Legislative  Leadership.  The  prominence  of  administration 
in  our  contemporary  political  system  does  not  imply  a  corresponding  de- 

11  Administrative  Powers  over  Persons  and  Property,  n.  584,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1928. 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  107 

cline  of  legislative  power.  On  the  contrary,  as  modern  government  has 
progressed  to  the  point  of  being  bigger  than  big  business,  the  scope  and 
magnitude  of  its  operations  render  farsighted  direction  ever  more  significant. 
If  we  may  speak  of  any  change  in  the  essential  nature  of  legislation,  thai 
change  would  lie  in  mounting  demands  on  legislative  leadership.  When 
administrative  agencies  touch  upon  the  activities  of  millions  of  citizens, 
it  is  a  matter  of  highest  concern  whether  or  not  the  legislative  marching 
orders  for  administrative  officials  are  framed  in  full  comprehension  and 
recognition  of  the  public  interest.  Ours  is  still  as  much  a  government  of 
laws  as  it  was  designed  to  be  by  those  who  formulated  the  Constitution. 

y  Administrative  power  is  not  self-generative.  No  government  agency  can 
take  action  without  a  statutory  foundation  for  action.  No  government 
agency  is  legally  free  to  push  action  beyond  either  the  bounds  of  lawful 
means  or  the  limitations  drawn  in  the  annual  budget  adopted  by  the  legis- 
lative branch.  ^  However,  statutory  definition  of  administrative  marching 
orders  can  draw  only  major  outlines.  It  would  be  unable  to  penetrate  into 
the  mountain  of  detail  that  is  necessary  for  effective  deployment  of  govern- 
mental forces  in  pursuit  of  objectives  laid  down  in  law.  Thus  the  legisla- 
ture is  called  upon  to  meet  the  complex  task  of  establishing  priorities  of 
goals  and  giving  general  direction  through  statutory  policy  pronouncements, 
while  at  the  same  time  allowing  administrators  sufficient  leeway  to  utilize 
their  agencies  to  the  best  possible  public  advantage.  Few  would  maintain 
in  the  face  of  this  task  that  the  service  state  is  apt  to  reduce  thT  legislative 
branch  to  the  function  of  dignified  ornament.  Active  government  sorely 
needs  wise  legislative  guidance. 

*^Role  of  tfte^Judidd  Power.  Nor  can  it  be  said  that  the  prominence  of 
administration  detracts  from  the  institutional  rank  of  the  judicial  power. 
To  be  sure,  the  judicial  power  may  isolate  itself.  Courts  have  always  tended 
to  gravitate  toward  becoming  exponents  of  conservative  attitudes.  If  any 
documentation  is  needed  in  this  respect,  it  may  be  found  in  the  history  of 
judicial  review  of  the  constitutionality  of  legislation.  In  fact,  in  the  past 
the  service  state  has  suffered  its  most  grievous  defeats  'from  the  recalcitrance 
of  the  judiciary.  The  memory  of  the  bitter  conflict  between  the  New  Deal 
and  the  Supreme  Court  is  still  fresh  in  our  minds.  That  conflict  could 
have  been  predicted,  for  during  the  New  Deal  we  tried  to  make  up  for  lost 
time  and  thus  advanced  at  a  more  rapid  pace.  What  was  new  was  not  the 
direction  of  the  advance  but  its  relative  speed.  As  the  speed  increased,  the 
courts  braced  themselves  to  intensify  their  traditional  braking  effect. 

Granting  that  no  court  is  safe  when  stepping  between  a  determined 
people  and  its  needs  and  aims,  there  remains  the  question  of  applying  judi- 
cial power  with  insight.  Administrative  agencies  must  be  kept  within  the 
scope  of  their  statutory  mandate  and  the  range  of  lawful  means,  but  this 
fact  should  not  lead  to  a  crippling  of  resourceful  public  management.  The 
judicial  power  denies  itself  opportunities  for  constructive  influence  in  ad- 


108  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

ministration  if  it  operates  primarily  as  a  restrictive  force.  Even  in  protect- 
ing the  citizens  against  illicit  encroachments,  the  judiciary  can  help  to  build 
a  positive  code  of  administrative  conduct.  In  the  service  state,  the  presence 
or  absence  of  a  code  of  this  kind  is  a  matter  of  great  consequence.  But 
courts  disqualify  themselves  from  making  a  decisive  contribution  to  the 
development  of  a  positive  administrative  code  when  they  permit  their  best 
energies  to  become  absorbed  in  efforts  to  block  the  growth  of  the  service 
state  on  principle. 

Resources  of  Administration.  As  an  instrument  of  government,  public 
administration  occupies  a  central  place  because  of  its  capacity  for  achieving 
results  by  direct  operations.  It  is  eminently  suited  to  function  as  an  agent 
of  policy,  to  give  policy  immediate  meaning  in  the  matrix  of  economic  and 
social  interrelations.  Not  being  tied  down  to  the  formalized  procedures 
appropriate  for  judicial  decisions,  it  is  elastic  in  its  approach.  It  is  the  gov- 
ernment's business  establishment  par  excellence.  Whereas  policy  can  only 
attempt  to  establish  a  general  rule,  administration  carries  the  application 
of  the  general  rule  into  the  boundless  diversity  of  concrete  situations.  In 
giving  specific  application  to  the  general  rule,  administration  can  take  into 
account  the  numerous  variables  of  different  conditions.  Because  of  this 
flexibility,  it  can  obtain  compliance  in  varying  situations  without  either 
jeopardizing  the  consistency  of  the  general  rule  or  making  the  general  rule  a 
crushing  force  that  strikes  everyone  and  everywhere  in  one  fell  swoop. 

Administration  as  a  Fitting  Process.  Administration  thus  presents  itself 
as  a  fitting  process — as  a  means  of  giving  policy  concise  expression  in  a 
highly  diversified  society.  Owing  to  this  characteristic,  administration  can- 
not live  without  discretion.  A  mechanical  tool  can  eat  its  way  through  a 
sheet  of  steel,  repeating  its  operation  with  never-changing  precision.  Ad- 
ministration, by  way  of  contrast,  deals  with  the  dynamics  of  an  organic 
society  made  up  of  human  beings.  Even  in  routine  transactions,  therefore, 
administrative  procedure  must  be  alert  to  the  dynamic  quality  of  economic 
and  social  life.  It  must  ascertain  facts  without  bias,  appraise  them  astutely, 
bring  policy  to  bear  upon  the  emerging  picture,  and  shape  its  decisions  in 
wakeful  appreciation  of  the  intent  of  policy  and  the  results  to  be  produced. 
..In  each  of  these  phases,  administration  must  aim  at  coherence  without  be- 
coming a  helpless  victim  of  precedent  and  operational  convenience.  In 
each  phase  it  must  keep  its  mentality  free  enough  for  innovation  and  con- 
stant improvement  of  methods  and  procedures.  In  each  phase  it  must  set 
its  course  in  such  a  way  as  to  prove  itself  the  servant  of  the  people.  A 
single  glance  at  any  of  these  postulates  is  all  we  need  in  order  to  understand 
the  necessity  for  securing  the  highest  caliber  of  administrative  stewardship. 

44.  THE  ENLISTMENT  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  JUDGMENT 

Legislative  Marching  Orders.  As  an  instrument  of  government,  public 
administration  moves  on  marching  orders  written  into  laws  and  regulations. 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION   OF   PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  109 

Being  the  agent  of  policy,  it  must  on  principle  accept  legislative  superin- 
tendence and  executive  command.  It  is  not  free  to  exercise  a  veto  power 
in  the  name  of  greater  expertise.  This  principle  is  easily  stated,  but  it  raises 
many  subtle  points  of  administrate  ethics.  Government  agencies,  respon- 
sible for  defined  areas  of  public  activity,  are  prone  to  develop  a  stake  in  their 
programs.  That  is  not  bad  in  itself,  because  administrators  will  on  the 
whole  render  better  service  when  they  have  faith  in  their  missions.  But  it 
is  also  true  that  their  whole-hearted  identification  with  the  task  assigned 
them  may  collide  with  their  obligation  to  bow  to  direction  whenever  such 
direction  reflects  changes  of  policy  which  rip  into  established  programs.  In 
situations  of  this  kind,  the  deeper  loyalty  of  service  must  triumph  over  sec- 
ondary loyalties  to  cherished  ends  and  means.  Administration  as  an  agent 
has  no  moral  right  to  plot  against  its  legislative  principal,  however  much  the 
principal  may  seem  to  be  in  error. 

This  does  not  mean  that  administration  is  free  to  use  its  mind  only  in 
performing  its  duty  as  an  agent  of  policy.  Throughout  the  business  estab- 
lishment of  government,  we  find  today  a  rich  assortment  of  staff  services 
of  high  quality.  No  less  impressive  is  the  store  of  sound  administrative 
judgment  derived  from  cumulative  experience.  Many  of  the  research  teams 
which  have  been  built  up  at  various  points  of  the  governmental  structure 
are  wholly  on  a  par  with  those  developed  in  the  realm  of  private  enterprise. 
In  the  supply  of  managerial  skill,  too,  government  has  ceased  to  be  gener- 
ally inferior  to  business.  How  obsolete  in  this  respect  the  beloved  catch- 
words of  bygone  days  are  is  attested  by  the  degree  of  unpublicized  informal 
cooperation  among  key  specialists  from  private  and  public  enterprise  in  a 
great  many  professional  associations.  Give-and-take  in  the  exchange  of 
helpful  information  has  become  a  mutual  process  from  which  government 
and  business  profit  alike  in  equal  proportions. 

Political  Feasibility  of  Policy.  With  so  much  pertinent  judgment  and 
experience  available  on  tap,  it  would  be  folly  to  insist  in  the  interest  of 
abstract  purity  of  functions  that  legislative  direction  should  never  nurture 
itself  by  resort  to  expert  counsel  coming  from  the  administrative  sphere. 
As  a  matter  of  fact,  such  counsel  is  constantly  sought  and  utilized  by  both 
the  legislature  and  the  chief  executive.  It  must  be  admitted,  however,  that  the 
chief  executive,  being  in  a  strategic  position,  can  more  expeditiously  equip 
himself  with  facilities  designed  to  make  available  for  his  use  the  whole  body 
of  administrative  information.  The  creation  in  1939  of  the  Executive  Office 
of  the  President  illustrates  the  way  in  which  facilities  of  this  character  may 
be  linked  with  the  head  of  the  government's  business  establishment.  Central 
staffs  attached  to  the  chief  executive  are  in  a  position  to  evolve  reporting 
relationships  with  the  departmental  system  through  which  appropriate  in- 
formation flows  up,  to  be  assembled  finally  into  a  comprehensive  picture. 
Much  of  this  information  is  immediately  translated  into  intelligence  to 
serve  internal  control  purposes.  A  considerable  volume,  however,  feeds 


110  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

into  the  policy-making  process,  either  by  pointing  up  issues  that  require 
solution  or  by  providing  supporting  data  for  tentatively  formulated  policy 
proposals. 

Successful  government  involves  the  accomplishment  of  feasible  objectives. 
Determination  of  feasibility  depends  on  a  number  of  factors.  Politically, 
a  feasible,  objective  is  one  that  is  wanted  by  sufficiently  strong  groups  of  the 
population  or  for  which  popular  endorsement  may  be  obtained  through 
effectively  stimulated  public  debate.  Determination  of  such  feasibility  is  a 
question  which  elected  representatives  of  the  people  are  generally  better  qual- 
ified to  decide  than  administrators.  It  includes,  for  example,  a  weighing 
among  goals  which  cannot  all  be  achieved  at  the  same  time.  Here,  again, 
political  sense  is  generally  more  important  than  administrative  experience. 
However,  once  political  feasibility  has  been  ascertained,  there  is  still  the 
problem  of  the  appropriate  governmental  approach.  Big  business  though 
it  is,  government,  like  any  other  business,  has  to  think  in  terms  of  available 
resources,  organizational  and  operational  as  well  as  financial. 

Administrative  Feasibility  of  Policy.  A  politically  feasible  objective  may 
not  be  attained  at  all  if  the  administrative  system  is  too  feeble  for  the  task. 
Even  stronger  administrative  machinery  may  be  dangerously  overworked 
if  a  politically  feasible  objective  of  considerable  magnitude  is  tackled  in 
one  reckless  effort.  It  may  be  necessary  to  progress  step  by  step,  and  to 
time  the  steps  at  wider  intervals.  On  each  of  these  points,  administrative 
judgment  is  able  to  contribute  substantially  to  the  determination  of  sound 
policy.  The  same  is  true  of  defining  the  administrative  pattern  that  will 
offer  the  greatest  insurance  of  straightforward  advance  toward  the  estab- 
lished goal.  Practical  alternatives  can  be  analyzed  before  action  is  taken. 
Such  planning  cuts  the  chance  of  breakdown  to  a  minimum.  It  also  pro- 
vides protection  against  costly  organizational  and  technical  errors.  In  short, 
it  is  a  valuable  aid  in  achieving  economy  of  effort. 

Blending  of  Judgments.  While  it  is  thus  clear  that  administrative  ad- 
vice is  an  important  ingredient  in  the  making  of  policy,  we  must  not  assume 
that  there  is  a  precise  borderline  between  consideration  of  political  feasibility 
and  examination  of  administrative  feasibility.  The  more  both  merge,  the 
better  will  be  the  end  result.  Because  administrative  advice  has  no  direct 
representation  in  the  political  councils,  it  must  be  drawn  in  systematically. 
Moreover,  legislative  bodies  must  keep  their  policy  planning  open  to  ad- 
ministrative alternatives  in  order  to  evolve  a  statutory  formula  that  will 
best  lend  itself  to  prompt  execution.  Conversely,  administrative  officials,  in 
advising  on  policy,  reduce  the  range  of  their  assistance  if  they  fail  to  give 
careful  thought  to  the  legislative  balance  of  power,  the  enunciated  or  antici- 
pated preferences  of  the  chief  executive,  and  the  probabilities  of  public  re- 
actions. Ideally,  political  and  administrative  thinking  should  blend  into 
i  joint  process. 

The  separation  of  powers  in  our  governmental  system  is  on  the  whole 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  111 

unfavorable  to  such  blending,  especially  when  legislative  and  executive 
prerogatives  are  jealously  guarded.  But  we  do  have  avenues  through  which 
we  can  come  near  the  ideal.  The  chief  executive  has  many  opportunities 
for  submitting  recommendations  to  the  legislative  branch;  these  may  be 
substantiated  by  extensive  staff  work.  The  legislature,  in  turn,  is  adequately 
equipped  in  its  committee  system  to  take  testimony  from  administrative 
officials  closest  to  the  subject  matter  under  discussion.  In  addition,  intimate 
though  unofficial  cooperation  between  the  staff  employed  by  legislative  com- 
mittees and  staffs  engaged  in  broader  studies  in  various  agencies  is  often 
fruitful.  This  checking  of  notes  and  interchange  of  findings  is  sometimes 
more  productive  than  public  presentation  of  testimony  before  legislative 
committees,  which  shape  their  basic  inferences  in  closed  executive  session. 
In  general,  however,  we  are  still  far  from  a  rational  scheme  through  which 
political  reasoning  and  administrative  judgment  can  be  merged  in  the  formu- 
lation of  policy.  Conceding  this  partial  failure,  it  is  well  to  recall  that,  in  the 
direction  of  government  business,  the  role  of  administrative  judgment  as  a 
source  of  informed  policy  decisions  has  steadily  expanded. 

Administrative  Freedom  of  Expression.  In  furnishing  counsel-on  policy 
matters,  administrative  officials  may  foster  perilous  illusions  if  their  en- 
vironment encourages  servility  and  spinelessness.  They  are  of  no  help 
whatsoever,  and  can  easily  turn  into  a  positive  menace,  when  conditions  in- 
duce them  to  echo  the  voices  of  the  mighty.  Administrative  judgment 
must  rest  on  unquestionable  integrity.  It  cannot  be  both  trustworthy  and 
pleasing  to  everyone.  It  must  enjoy  freedom  of  expression.  Advice  amounts 
to  nothing  when  it  is  fearful  of  disagreement.  The  climate  of  administrative 
judgment  is  not  made  by  administrators  alone.  It  is  the  product  .of  many 
things:  public  attitudes  toward  the  government's  business  establishment; 
cartoons  and  editorials;  aggressive  and  defensive  propaganda  coming  from 
particular  special  interests;  legislative  resentments;  administrative  self- 
complacency.  Sometimes  we  run  into  deep-rooted  doubts  whether  our 
national  ways  and  habits,  especially  in  the  legislative  sphere,  leave  room  for 
public  administrators  who  pour  their  hearts  into  their  work,  think  for 
themselves,  and  make  no  bones  about  the  state  of  affairs  and  what  ought  to 
be  done  about  it.  These  doubts  may  merely  indicate  the  obvious — that  the 
service  state  is  still  in  its  youth.  But  we  cannot  escape  the  conclusion  that 
when  there  is  competence  for  counsel  on  policy  in  our  administrative  system, 
it  is  only  commonsense  to  use  and  strengthen  it. 

5.  THE  CONTRIBUTION  OF  SERVICE 

Popular  Basis  of  Administrative  Services.  A  fairly  detailed  listing  of  all 
of  the  services  performed  by  government— federal,  state  and  local— would 
fill  many  pages.  None  of  these  services  was  forced  upon  the  community  by 
wild-eyed  officialdom.  Each  came  into  being  in  response  to  public  demands 


112  THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

to  which  legislative  bodies  paid  deference— a  perfectly  natural  development 
in  a  democracy. 

The  power  of  votes  and  the  threat  of  reprisals  in  subsequent  electoral 
campaigns  hang  like  dark  clouds  over  the  legislative  scene.  If  every  public 
demand  could  be  subjected  to  popular  referendum,  many  loudly  advocated 
propositions  might  die  a  natural  death  without  gaining  striking  power  in 
pressure  politics.  But  the  vast  bulk  of  legislation  is  handled  by  representa- 
tive assemblies  exposed  to  minority  agitation,  while  the  public  at  large  is 
normally  amorphous  and  unorganized.  It  is  divided  by  conflicting  loyalties 
that  pull  simultaneously  toward  party,  class,  general  inclination  of  outlook, 
real  or  imagined  self-advancement,  religious  denomination,  occupational 
organization,  and  an  abundance  of  other  interests,  large  and  small.  In  this 
bewildering  and  ever-changing  pattern  the  public  falls  apart  into  many 
publics.  And  the  better  organized  for  political  pressure  each  public  is,  the 
greater  is  its  chance  of  overriding  the  public  at  large.  This  explains  in  the 
main  the  failure  of  straight  consumer  representation  in  the  political  arena. 
It  also  explains  why  the  service  state  is  neither  of  one  cast  nor  free  from 
inconsistencies. 

Habit  of  Self-Restraint.  Of  course,  it  would  be  a  strange  misconception 
to  contend  that  the  test  of  democracy  is  abstract  wisdom.  As  individuals,  we 
commit  sad  errors  of  judgment  in  matters  of  great  importance,  do  foolish 
things  for  unaccountable  reasons,  cling  tenaciously  to  absurd  prejudices, 
cast  prudence  to  the  winds  when  we  feel  like  it.  Can  we  hope  to  do  much 
better  collectively?  Actually,  we  do  somewhat  better  in  the  realm  of  public 
affairs  because  here  reason  follows  us  like  a  faithful  dog.  Here  there  is 
considerably  more  argument  and  counterargument  than  we  would  be 
willing  to  put  up  with  in  our  private  affairs.  And  here  we  also  have  more 
free  advice  from  authoritative  sources — the  League  of  Women  Voters,  the 
National  Association  of  Manufacturers,  the  Secretary  of  State,  our  Congress- 
man, the  head  of  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics,  to  mention  but  a  few. 
Sometimes  we  entirely  change  our  minds  on  such  advice,  though  even  when 
we  do  we  usually  line  up  with  the  side  that  promises  us  the  largest  slice 
of  cake.  Yet  we  are  on  the  whole  rather  particular  about  the  price  of  the 
cake  and  more  anxious  to  restrain  our  appetites  than  we  are  in  our  private 
spending. 

This  relative  eagerness  for  self-restraint  is  a  wholesome  tendency.  It 
should  be  no  more  than  that.  For  a  considerable  time,  especially  the  closing 
decades  of  the  past  century  when  our  great  economic  interests  reaped  the 
harvest  of  our  continent,  the  masters  of  new  fortunes  tried  to  convince  us 
that  we  had  to  make  this  tendency  toward  political  self-abnegation  into 
an  axiom  of  governance.  (They  argued  that  the  best  government  would  be 
one  that  governs  least,  one  that  entrusts  control  to  the  natural  drift  of  the 
economy  and  the  profit  motive.  Only  when  it  became  apparent  that  we 


THE   SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  113 

fared  none  too  well  under  this  prescription  did  we  cast  about  for  a  better 
one. 

Governmental  Reinforcement  of  the  Enterprise  Economy.  Thus  the 
structure  of  our  public  services  came  forth  without  a  supporting  ideology, 
even  running  counter  to  the  general  undertone  of  domestic  propaganda.  We 
bought  the  service  state  in  relatively  small  pieces,  each  piece  being  badly 
needed  to  fill  cracks  and  breaches  in  the  industrial  order.  The  mixed  econ- 
omy took  form,  not  because  we  thought  it  good,  but  because  necessity  dic- 
tated successive  reinforcements  of  the  private  sector  through  governmental 
action  which  added  to  the  public  sector.  The  service  contribution  of  admin- 
istrative agencies,  viewed  as  a  whole,  lies  primarily  in  its  functon  as  a  broad 
support  of  the  enterprise  economy. 

It  may  be  presumed  that  private  business  would  be  able  to  run  our 
unemployment  and  old-age  insurance  schemes  as  well  as  does  government — 
if  there  were  sufficient  profit  in  it.  It  might  be  conceivable  for  business  to 
service  itself  on  some  cooperative  basis  in  about  the  same  way  that  it  is 
being  serviced  at  public  expense  by  such  agencies  as  the  Department  of 
Commerce.  It  is  perhaps  possible  for  the  several  large  farmer  organizations 
to  maintain  specialized  staffs  that  could  jointly  undertake  the  job  now  done 
by  such  establishments  as  the  Bureau  of  Plant  Industry,  Soils,  and  Agricul- 
tural Engineering.  However,  if  we  think  in  the  perspective  of  the  total 
picture  of  national  efficiency,  it  is  not  difficult  to  spot  the  comparative  weak- 
ness of  such  solutions.  Each  of  these  governmental  services — and  they  are 
examples  chosen  at  random — benefits  not  only  from  direct  access  to  data  and 
experience  accruing  in  public  activities,  but  also  operates  under  standards 
of  strict  accounting  to  the  public  at  large.  Cost  accounting  under  budgetary 
control  and  expenditure  justification  to  the  satisfaction  of  the  legislature  are 
not  in  themselves  the  most  important  factors.  More  significant  is  the  gen- 
eral atmosphere  of  public  accountability.  Government  cannot  afford  to 
chisel  on  its  data.  It  cannot  safely  underwrite  the  interests  of  individual 
groups.  It  must  come  very  close  to  scientific  accuracy  and  impartial  service 
to  all. 

Benefits  of  Regulation.  This  is  true  also  of  the  regulatory  process.  Regu- 
lation has  sometimes  been  slapped  down  on  interests  which  have  outraged 
our  sense  of  equity,  but  punitive  regulation  has  always  tended  to  throw  new 
burdens  of  ill-feeling  on  the  community  and  to  overstep  its  legitimate  aims 
in  the  heat  of  battle.  Ordinarily,  the  punitive  impetus  does  not  survive  for 
any  length  of  t;me,  and  methods  are  later  adjusted  to  meet  the  practical 
business  at  hand.  We  need  only  look  at  the  relationships  between  carriers 
and  shippers  on  the  one  hand  and  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 
on  the  other.12 

12  Some  very  pertinent  observations  are  contained  in  a  recent  tribute  to  a  great  adminis- 
trator who  died  in  hprness:  S wisher,  Carl  B.,  "Joseph  B.  Eastman:  Public  Servant,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  34  ff. 


114  TK£  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

Evidence  shows  that  regulatory  bodies,  when  they  have  established  them- 
selves, develop  a  peculiar  predilection  for  those  subject  to  their  powers. 
This  is  hardly  surprising.  The  function  of  regulation  is  to  police — in  the 
interest  of  a  healthy  state  of  affairs.  The  goal  is  constructive,  and  the  pro- 
cedure must  correspond  to  it.  Even  if  regulatory  bodies  come  to  see  the 
public  welfare  to  some  extent  from  the  angle  of  the  welfare  of  those  to  be 
regulated,  they  nevertheless  resist  the  temptation  to  give  away  their  birth- 
rights* To  steady  them  when  they  need  steadying  is  the  task  of  the 
legislature  or,  more  precisely,  of  free  public  criticism. 

Popular  Accountability  of  Administration.  The  service  motive  is  not  an 
exclusive  property  of  government.  No  big  company  today  overlooks  oppor- 
tunities for  selling  itself  on  claims  of  superior  service.  We  hear  these  claims 
everyday  in  the  commercial  plugs  over  the  radio;  we  read  them  on  trolley 
and  bus  posters  and  in  the  smooth-voiced  advertisements  of  popular  maga- 
zines. Business  wants  to  serve — as  well  as  government.  However,  as  cus- 
tomers and  consumers  we  have  much  more  direct  control  over  public 
business  and  public  services  than  private  enterprise  would  be  willing  to 
allow.  We  have  a  sharp  eye  on  our  public  servants,  and  they  know  it.  We 
can  chastise  them  with  assured  effect  through  public  complaint  and  legis- 
lative grilling.  We  can  take  business  away  from  them  by  cutting  down 
appropriations.  We  may  often  censure  too  rashly,  but  the  irascible  temper 
which  we  habitually  reserve  for  governmental  errors  and  failings  keeps 
administrative  officials  on  their  toes.  Administration '  cannot  withhold  its 
books  from  public  inspection.  We  can  force  responsive  service. 

6.  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION — SOCIAL  BUFFER 

Fountains  of  Administrative  Knowledge.  The  broad  spread  of  govern- 
mental activities  in  the  service  state  has  had  consequences  extending  beyond 
the  mere  expansion  of  public  services.  When  government  is  interposed  at 
many  points  in  our  society,  it  gains  extraordinary  opportunities  for  devel- 
oping a  system  of  intelligence  whose  output  becomes  public  knowledge. 
Take  something  as  vital  as  dependable  statistics  on  unemployment.  Before 
the  more  than  400,000  Smiths,  together  with  the  Joneses,  the  Thompsons,  and 
the  rest  of  us,  had  been  duly  entered  in  the  central  records  of  the  Social 
Security  Board,  we  had  to  guess  at  the  volume  of  unemployment.  Now,  as 
an  incidental  by-product  of  our  social  security  scheme,  we  can  always  know, 
with  a  high  degree  of  exactness.  Fortified  with  up-to-date  information, 
government  is  in  a  position  to  plan  policy  with  considerable  assurance.  It 
is  also  able  to  obtain  early  warning  of  impending  slumps  and  take  remedial 
action  before  being  overtaken  by  events.  It  can  even  put  its  finger  on 
specific  areas  where  maladjustments  have  become  acute,  and  probe  into 
underlying  causes. 

Government's  Intelligence  Function-  The  intelligence  function  of  mod- 
ern government  is  in  many  ways  crucial  to  the  fate  of  the  economic  and 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION          115 

social  order.  Jeremy  Bentham  saw  it  in  this  light  more  than  a  century  ago 
It  lies  at  the  heart  of  our  attempts  at  achieving  a  high  level  of  employment 
in  the  postwar  period.   The  role  of  the  federal  government  in  attaining 
maximum  employment  is  predicated  on  the  availability  of  a  large  array  of 
detailed  statistical  data  on  such  activities  as  consumer  spending;  business 
expenditures  and  outlays — including  construction,  additions  to  inventories, 
and  exports;  and  state  and  local  expenditures — including  projected  public 
works.   Moreover,  retrospective  data  alone  would  not  be  adequate.  They 
must  be  supplemented  by  date  which  predict  future  facts.   We  would  be 
stopped  in  our  tracks  and  left  to  face  complete  uncertainty  if  the  entire 
body  of  government  intelligence  were  still  in  the  state  which  existed  only 
fifteen  years  ago.  Today  we  are  better  prepared,  because  government,  in  its 
interlocking  with  the  enterprise  economy,  has  multiplied  its  eyes  and  added 
finer  lenses. 

Public  Research  and  Analysis.  The  more  it  knows,  the  better  govern- 
ment can  judge.  Seeing  more,  it  is  no  longer  so  easily  eluded  by  those 
whose  doings  shy  from  light,  nor  is  it  quickly  misled  and  confused  by  the 
assertions  of  optimists  and  pessimists  alike.  Capitalizing  on  its  far-flung 
intelligence,  government  can  substantiate  its  hunches  and  projections,  and 
is  less  helpless  in  rebuttal.  In  our  civilization,  reseanh  and  analysis  of  in- 
formation, together  with  scientific  fact-gathering  and  wider  dissemination 
of  knowledge,  are  national  resources  of  the  greatest  practical  value  because 
they  give  our  hand  a  surer  touch  in  shaping  our  institutional  and  technolo- 
gical environment.  Truth  is  an  objectifying  influence  in  the  identification 
of  the  public  interest  and  the  pursuit  of  public  ends.  It  takes  the  wind 
out  of  the  sails  of  partisan  clamor  and  intentional  or  unintentional  mis- 
representation. 

The  acquisition  of  knowledge  is  a  field  of  primary  concern  to  demo- 
cratic government.  Its  ascendancy  was  properly  stressed  in  the  epoch- 
making  report  of  Great  Britain's  Machinery  of  Government  Committee 
under  Haldane's  chairmanship  at  the  end  of  World  War  I.13  Our  experi- 
ence in  World  War  II  with  the  Office  of  Scientific  Research  and  Develop- 
ment, established  for  the  purpose  of  securing  adequate  provision  for  research 
on  scientific  and  medical  problems  relating  to  national  defense,  represents 
a  memorable  step  in  the  same  direction.  But  research  must  not  be  confined 
to  laboratories  alone.  The  whole  business  establishment  of  government, 
although  it  is  in  business  for  business'  sake,  is  at  the  same  time  a  gigantic 
test  tube  with  which  we  gradually  expand  our  social  knowledge.  In  this 
way  we  not  only  augment  the  body  of  information  to  guide  the  policy- 
making  authorities;  we  also  set  down  increasingly  definite  terms  of  refer- 
ence for  legitimate  public  discussion.  It  is  harder  to  fool  the  people  when 


18  Cd.  9230,  London:  His  Majesty's  Stationery  Office,  1918. 


116          THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

authentic  facts  and  figures  make  lies  and  wild  statements  uncomfortable 
for  their  authors. 

Getting  ct  the  facts.  Through  its  administrative  system,  government 
has  been  able  to  organize  its  intelligence  function.  Without  something  like 
the  administrative  machinery  which  we  have  built  up  over  the  years,  gov- 
ernment intelligence  would  necessarily  be  secondhand  and  thus  of  dubious 
merit.  The  risk  of  accepting  at  its  face  value  the  brief  of  an  interest  group 
or  the  complaint  of  a  constituent  is  well  known  to  every  seasoned  lawmaker. 
With  literally  hundreds  of  thousands  of  government  employees  in  daily 
touch  with  countless  economic  and  social  activities  and  various  elements  of 
the  population,  headquarters  offices  meet  few  obstacles  in  providing  for 
continuing  public  reconnaissance,  in  gauging  pressures  and  tensions  in  the 
industrial  order,  and  in  getting  at  the  relevant  facts.  On  the  other  hand, 
general  awareness  by  the  public  of  the  intelligence  function  of  government 
has  a  restraining  effect  on  the  voraciousness  of  special  interests  and  the  char- 
acter of  pressure-group  rationalizations.  To  this  extent,  administration  places 
itself  deliberately  between  contending  forces,  each  of  which  could  have  its 
way  only  at  the  expense  of  all  of  us. 

More  explicit  and  more  direct  is  the  buffer  function  of  the  administrative 
system  in  the  immediate  exercise  of  authority,  either  of  a  regulatory  nature 
or  as  the  basis  of  concrete  services.  Here  government,  by  being  on  the 
scene,  enforces  the  ground  rules  of  democratic  society.  This  task  includes 
not  only  the  job  of  safeguarding  defined  standards  of  human  conduct  and 
decent  living  but  also  that  of  preserving  the  essential  framework  of  indi- 
vidual initiative  and  accomplishment.  ^Administrative  power  is  brought  to 
bear  upon  the  economic  power  wielded  by  giant  organizations  which,  if 
left  unchecked,  would  play  havoc  with  the  basic  interests  of  the  individual 
as  well  as  with  those  of  the  community  at  large^It  is  true,  of  course,  that 
administrative  agencies  are  not  always  strong  enough  to  muster  unyielding 
resistance  under  the  impact  of  determined  pressures.14  But  we  should  not 
lose  sight  of  the  fact  that  in  the  struggle  of  organized  forces  for  superiority, 
government  has  gone  far  toward  running  interference  for  the  underdog. 

Concern  for  the  Underdog.  Concern  for  the  underdog  is  deeply  in- 
grained in  our  American  mores.  It  gives  our  political  thinking  a  distinctive 
flavor.  Yet,  in  the  day-by-day  operation  of  our  economy  we  are  inclined 
to  a  startling  degree  to  condone  ruthless  prosecution  of  selfish  ends.  A  broad 
strand  of  our  social  philosophy  supports  the  fears  which  Louis  Brandeis 
aptly  expressed  in  speaking  of  the  curse  of  bigness.  It  is  equally  American, 
however,  to  write  bigness  in  big  letters—to  take  pride  in  the  colossal  and 
still  greater  pride  in  the  super-colossal.  The  native  soil  has  favored  the 
growth  of  economic  empires  in  our  midst,  and  the  captains  of  these  empires 
have  ranked  above  our  politicians.  When  we  enshrine  bigness  as  we  did 

14  The  best  study  of  this  problem  is  Herring,  E.  Pendleton,  Public  Administration  and  the 
Public  Interest.  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1936. 


THE  SOCIAL  FUNCTION  OF  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION  117 

in  the  days  of  laissez  faire,  we  cancel  the  buffer  function  of  the  administra- 
tive system.  Public  officials,  however  firmly  established  their  service  ideology 
may  be,  cannot  withdraw  into  the  ivory  tower.  They  cannot  defy  public 
opinion  or  what  successfully  poses  for  it.  How  well  administration  per- 
forms its  buffer  functions  is,  therefore,  mainly  up  to  all  of  us. 

Our  conflicting  reactions  toward  bigness  have  never  quite  permitted  us 
to  seek  the  ultimate  criterion  of  effective  organization  in  its  contribution 
to  the  life  of  the  common  man.  There  have  been  times  when  shrewd  play 
on  our  emotions  made  us  more  fearful  of  big  government  than  of  big 
business.  One  thing  is  clear,  however.  If  ours  is  to  be  a  common  man's 
democracy,  government  must  be  big  enough  to  measure  up  to  the  order 
of  magnitude  prevailing  in  the  economic  sphere. 


Pan  H 

ORGANIZATION  AND  MANAGEMENT 


CHAPTER 


Planning  and  Administration 

1.  THE  IMPORTANCE  OF  PLANNING 

Essence  of  Planning.  Planning  is  preparation  for  action.  It  is  the  vital 
step  in  any  great  enterprise,  for  many  subsequent  decisions  about  organiza- 
tion, procedure,  personnel,  and  policies  must  flow  from  an  original  concep- 
tion of  purpose.  All  administrative  agencies  are  set  up  to  accomplish  some 
desired  goal.  In  a  sense,  all  the  problems  of  administration  are  problems 
of  translating  purpose  into  action.  The  first  concern  of  administrators  at 
all  times  is  raising  and  answering  the  question,  "What  am  I  expected  to 
accomplish?"  The  second  concern  is,  "How  shall  I  accomplish  it?" 

Planning  gives  meaning  to  action.  The  work  done  by  an  administrative 
agency  will  achieve  its  goals  only  if  careful  plans  have  been  prepared  which 
show  what  is  to  be  accomplished.  Otherwise,  there  may  be  much  action 
of  all  kinds,  but  few  results.  Or  the  many  activities  undertaken  may  lead 
to  contradictory  results. 

Planning  is  a  technique  or  process.  In  itself,  the  word  "planning"  sug- 
gests no  goals.  It  merely  means  that  some  method  is  followed  which  re- 
sults in  determining  what  is  wanted  and  in  a  plan  of  action  for  reaching 
that  desired  goal.  Planning  is  a  method  of  approaching  problems — a 
method  which  says,  "Let  us  define  clearly  what  it  is  we  wish  to  do,"  and 
then  asks,  "What  steps  shall  we  take  in  order  to  accomplish  our  purpose?" 

Planning  is  continuous.  Just  as  life  is  dynamic  and  everchanging,  so 
must  planning  by  individuals  and  by  organized  groups  be  dynamic.  Early 
plans  may  become  inadequate  as  new  factors  in  any  situation  are  discovered, 
as  changing  circumstances  occur,  as  we  grow  and  learn  more  about  the 
environment  in  which  we  live.  Plans  must  accordingly  be  modified  from 
time  to  time.  Periodic  or  even  continuous  review  of  fundamental  purposes 
is  desirable  for  any  institution  or  any  group  in  order  to  ensure  that  the 
work  done  will  meet  present  conditions  and  needs. 

Planning  embraces  all  aspects  of  human  life.  It  concerns  every  phase 
of  activity  in  which  we  participate,  both  individually  and  as  organized 

121 


122  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

groups.  The  subjects  of  concern  in  the  planning  work  of  the  federal  gov- 
ernment before  World  War  II  are  well  illustrated  in  a  symposium  on  the 
topic  published  in  194L1  The  chapter  titles  included  land  planning,  water 
resources,  energy  resources,  industrial  policies,  savings  and  capital  forma- 
tion, income  distribution,  employment  planning,  public  works,  transporta- 
tion needs,  agricultural  adjustment,  population,  nutrition,  housing,  educa- 
tion, health,  recreation,  social  security,  international  economic  relations,  war 
planning,  and  industrial  mobilization  for  defense.  These  were  all  subjects 
of  some  degree  of  planning  in  the  federal  government.  State  and  local 
governments  had  many  of  the  same  concerns  and  others  as  well.  Private 
groups,  from  the  great  corporations  to  fraternal  societies,  had  and  have 
their  plans.  An  account  of  the  steps  taken  by  one  large  corporation,  the 
General  Electric  Company,  in  reviewing  its  plans  and  in  formulating  new 
ones  on  the  eve  of  World  War  II  well  illustrates  planning  by  private 
enterprise.2 

Since  those  who  direct  organized  efforts  must  begin  by  planning  them, 
planning  is  the  first  responsibility  of  management.  The  continuing  concern 
with  planning  which  every  alert  and  efficient  agency  must  manifest  is  well 
recognized  today  in  every  discussion  dealing  with  the  subject  of  manage- 
ment. For  example,  a  recent  survey  of  the  organization  and  direction  of 
some  twenty  business  corporations  declares  it  to  be  the  primary  responsi- 
bility of  top  management  to  provide: 

.  .  .  far-sighted  planning  and  clarification  of  objectives,  visualizing  the 
needs  of  the  business  and  determining  its  most  advantageous  future 
course.  . . .  There  is  nothing  about  an  organization  more  important  than 
its  future.  Owners,  management,  employees,  and  society  in  general  are, 
or  should  be,  more  concerned  about  where  a  company  is  going  than 
where  it  has  been. . .  .3 

Similarly,  a  searching  discussion  of  administration  in  the  field  of  munici- 
pal public  works  makes  this  generalization: 

The  successful  management  and  control  of  any  large  enterprise  re- 
quires carefully  prepared  plans  which  seek  to  forecast  its  future  opera- 
tions as  accurately  as  possible.4 

These  elementary  propositions  may  be  illustrated  by  a  simple  and  famil- 
iar analogy.  The  construction  of  a  house  is  first  of  all  a  matter  of  planning. 
There  are  such  fundamental  questions  to  answer  as  how  many  and  what 
types  of  rooms,  what  kind  of  exterior,  what  kind  of  surroundings,  the 
special  features  desired,  and  the  amount  which  can  be  spent  out  of  available 

*  Galloway,  George  B.  and  Associates,  Planning  for  America,  New  York:  Henry  Holt,  1941. 

2  See  Prince,  David  E.,  "Planning  for  the  Future  While  Producing  for  Victory,"  in  National 
Conference  on  Planning,  1942,  p.  48  ff.t  Chicago:  American  Society  of  Planning  Officials,  1942. 

3  Holden,  Paul  E.,  Fish,  Lounsbury  S.  and  Smith,  Hubert  L.,  Top  Management  Organization 
and  Control t  p.  3,  Stanford:  Stanford  University  Press,  1941. 

4  Stone,  Donald  C.,  The  Management  of  Municipal  Public  Works,  p.  63,  Chicago:  Public 
Administration  Service,  1939. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  123 

resources.  The  location  is  then  selected,  and  detailed  plans  are  prepared 
to  fit  the  wants  of  the  owner  and  the  peculiar  requirements  of  the  site. 
The  architect's  blueprints  are  the  starting  point  for  the  contractor  who 
actually  builds  the  house,  who  translates  purpose  into  action.  Later,  the 
house  may  be  outmoded,  or  may  lack  the  latest  developments  in  heating  and 
lighting.  It  may  not  be  large  enough.  The  income  status  of  the  owner 
may  change.  Then  it  must  be  remodeled,  or  a  new  house  designed  and  built. 
In  all  of  these  phases  of  providing  ourselves  with  shelter,  we  practice  the 
fundamentals  of  planning. 

Contribution  of  Administrative  Planning.  No  informed  discussion  of 
public  administration  can  fail  to  give  specific  attention  to  the  problems  of 
planning.  In  many  respects  these  problems  are  common  to  all  phases  of 
administrative  activity — they  involve  organizational  structure,  personnel, 
personalities  and  relationships  between  units  of  an  organization.  The  rea- 
sons for  isolating  the  subject  of  planning  for  special  mention  as  the  opening 
chapter  of  this  part  on  organization  and  management  should  therefore 
be  obvious.  When  we  talk  about  the  problems  of  public  administration 
we  look  toward  the  techniques  and  processes  involved  in  carrying  out  the 
programs  of  government.  But  we  must  never  lose  sight  of  the  fact  that 
we  begin  with  the  program,  with  the  work  our  government  desires  to  accom- 
plish. Our  primary  interest  may  be  confined  to  the  process  of  performance, 
yet  that  process  is  important  only  if  it  attains  the  purpose  or  end  of  admin- 
istrative activity.  Sometimes  students  of  administration  become  so  pre- 
occupied with  procedures  and  processes  that  they  foget  what  is  of  first 
importance — the  results  of  these  processes. 

By  beginning  our  treatment  of  organization  and  management  with  the 
subject  of  planning,  we  are  acknowledging  that  our  first  concern  is  with 
results.  For,  as  we  said  earlier,  planning  is  preparation  for  action.  It  is  a 
particular  phase  of  management,  which  must  continuously  deal  with  defin- 
ing end  and  purpose,  with  setting  the  goals  to  be  realized.  Administrative 
performance  can  be  measured  only  in  terms  of  the  extent  to  which  these 
goals  have  been  achieved.  As  one  of  the  processes  of  administration,  plan- 
ning deserves  emphasis  because  of  its  tremendous  influence  upon  all  admin- 
istrative activity.  The  more  carefully  the  plans  are  prepared,  the  less  waste 
will  appear  in  accomplishment.  The  more  comprehensive  the  plans,  the 
less  day-to-day  improvisation  will  be  necessary  and  the  fewer  crises  will 
occur.  The  more  adequate  our  plans,  the  surer  we  will  be  of  accom- 
plishing our  purpose. 

In  reviewing  the  quality  of  any  administrative  agency,  the  analyst  today 
usually  begins  with  these  questions:  "What  steps  are  taken  to  define  the 
purpose  and  objectives  of  the  agency?  Is  there  a  plan  of  action?  How 
comprehensive  is  the  plan?  Is  the  program  reviewed  from  time  to  time?" 
These  and  similar  questions  are  vital  because  all  other  problems— including 
problems  in  structural  arrangement,  budgeting,  personnel,  reporting,  and 


124  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

worMhig  relationships— must  be  examined  in  the  light  of  their  influence 
upon  realizing  the  plans  of  the  agency. 

Planning  and  Legislation.  Just  what  kind  of  planning  does  an  admin- 
istrative agency  do?  What  about  the  role  of  the  legislature  in  our  scheme 
of  government?  For  one  thing,  in  recent  years  the  advance  planning  of  the 
broad  objectives  of  national  action  has  become  more  and  more  a  function 
of  the  executive  branch  of  our  government.  To  such  planning  all  adminis- 
trative agencies  contribute.  The  same  tendency  has  developed  in  state 
and  local  governments.5  The  legislature  today  reviews,  criticizes,  and  modi- 
fies the  plans  prepared  by  administrative  agencies  under  the  coordinative 
responsibility  of  the  chief  executive.  The  greater  prominence  of  this  pro- 
cedure since  1933  has  not  resulted  from  any  peculiarities  of  the  New  Deal, 
but  from  the  conditions  of  dynamic  government  confronted  with  more  and 
more  problems  requiring  national  action — problems  ranging  from  unem- 
ployment to  war. 

Increasingly  the  role  of  the  legislature  is  one  of  criticism  rather  than  of 
formulation.  For  many  reasons,  we  have  found  that  legislatures  by  them- 
selves are  not  in  a  position  to  formulate  broad  programs  of  action.  This, 
of  course,  does  not  mean  the  inevitable  destruction  of  democratic  govern- 
ment. Even  when  administrative  agencies  do  the  planning,  the  final  author- 
ity to  approve  or  disapprove  each  proposal  remains  a  legislative  function. 
This  is  a  very  real  and  essential  authority,  not  to  be  disparaged. 

Planning  and  Administration.  In  addition  to  the  need  for  administrative 
agencies  to  plan  broad  objectives  for  legislative  consideration  and  sanction, 
there  is  the  need  for  planning  the  details  within  the  legislative  framework. 
Frequently  legislatures  set  forth  their  will  in  very  general  terms.  The  dif- 
ferences of  opinion  among  lawmakers  and  the  pressures  of  various  groups 
converging  on  a  legislature  often  prevent  agreement  except  upon  certain 
main  purposes.  The  details,  or  the  refinements,  are  left  to  be  worked  out. 
Such  wartime  problems,  for  example,  as  the  size  of  Army  and  Navy,  the 
composition  of  the  military  forces,  and  the  type  of  weapons  and  equipment 
needed  were  left  for  administrative  determination.  They  required  careful 
planning. 

Then,  in  the  third  place,  there  are  the  administrative  plans  in  a  more 
specific  sense,  the  programs  of  work  laid  out  to  achieve  the  objectives  finally 
agreed  upon.  These  administrative  plans  may  include  th»e  budget,  the 
organization  structure,  and  a  time  schedule  of  work  accomplishment.  This 
is  preeminently  a  job  of  administration.  It  should  never  be  attempted  on 
the  legislative  level. 

Interrelation  of  Planning  Activities.  All  these  types  of  planning  are 
closely  related.  The  interplay  of  administrative  planning,  review  of  present 
programs,  and  formulation  of  new  objectives  goes  on  all  the  time.  Often 

5  Sec,  for  example,  the  experience  in  New  York  State  as  set  forth  by  Scott,  Elisabeth  M. 
and  Zellcr,  Belle,  "State  Agencies  and  Lawmaking,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1942,  Vol. 
2,  p.  205  ff. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  125 

a  sense  of  the  desired  goals  of  administrative  action  is  developed  ouf$f  the 
work  of  an  agency.  We  have  on  occasion  established  agencies  with  the 
expectation  that  they  will  develop  plans  for  action  and  obtain  legislation 
for  a  desired  program.  This  was  true,  for  instance,  in  the  field  of  price 
control  during  World  War  II. 

It  must  be  repeated — planning  presupposes  no  particular  set  of  objectives, 
nor  any  one  conception  of  political  values.  Just  as  budgeting  in  and  of 
itself  does  not  mean  large  outlay  or  small  outlay,  revenues  balanced  with 
expenditures,  or  deficit  spending,  so  planning  does  not  necessarily  mean 
either  a  collectivist  or  a  laisscz  faire  economy.  There  has  been  much  con- 
fusion on  this  score  in  recent  years.  The  attention  given  the  succession  of 
Five-Year  Plans  in  the  Soviet  Union  seems  to  have  suggested  to  many  that 
planning  and  communism  are  synonymous.  The  discovery  that  Hitler's 
Germany  also  planned  in  a  similar  way  merely  broadened  the  association 
to  include  all  totalitarian  forms  of  government. 

Those  who  would  insist  that  planning  is  incompatible  with  our  form 
of  government  not  only  appear  to  contend  that  democracy  is  planlessness 
but  also  show  themselves  little  versed  in  American  history.  It  has  often 
been  pointed  out  that  Alexander  Hamilton's  First  Report  on  Public  Credit 
in  1790,  two  other  public  reports  presented  in  that  year,  and  his  great  Report 
on  Manufactures  in  1791  were  all  planning  documents  of  the  first  impor- 
tance. These  were  just  the  beginning  of  planning  by  the  new  American 
government — planning  that  has  been  continuing  ever  since. 

The  furor  about  planning  is  caused  by  disagreement  over  objectives 
and  methods.  Debate  is  desirable  in  a  democracy.  But  it  should  not  suggest 
that  planning  in  itself  is  undesirable.  We  may  weigh  specific  plans;  but 
we  should  be  agreed  that  planning  is  necessary  and  vital  in  public  admin- 
istration.8 As  a  problem  in  administration,  distinguished  from  the  man) 

8  As  long  as  we  have  government  and  administrative  agencies,  we  must  have  planning. 
This  planning  may  be  of  two  types:  it  may  be  concerned  with  new  programs  and  new 
activities  to  meet  particular  problems  demanding  governmental  a»tcnuon;  or  it  may  be  concerned 
with  the  progrrms  for  carrying  out  broad  objectives  already  set  forth  in  legislation.  The  second 
type  of  planning  in  particular  is  absolutely  indispensable  to  efficient  administration.  The  first 
type  is  closely  related  to  fundamental  issues  of  public  policy,  and  the  eventual  decision  must 
be  made  by  the  chief  executive  and  the  legislative  body.  This  type  of  planning  is  intended 
to  facilitate  the  selection  of  choices  by  those  responsible  for  public  policy. 

There  have  been  recently  several  vigorous  denunciations  of  "planners."  See  particularly 
Mises,  Ludwig  von,  Bureaucracy,  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press,  1944,  and  Hayek, 
Friedrich  A.,  The  Road  to  Serfdom,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1944.  The  real 
object  of  attack  in  these  volumes  is  a  government  policy  which  seeks  positively  to  influence 
the  operation  of  our  economic  system.  Such  policy  is  identified  as  government  economic 
planning,  and  immediately  suggests  to  the  authors  that  all  planners  are  engaged  in  promoting 
government  control  of  prices,  production,  service  industries,  and  capital  formation.  Actually, 
the  authors  are  attacking  certain  governmental  policies.  The  debate  accordingly  should  be 
confined  to  these  policies,  and  should  not  degenerate  into  name-calling  directed  against  ill- 
dentificd  "planners.1* 

It  should  perhaps  be  repeated  that  no  existing  duties  assigned  to  the  executive  branch  of 
the  government  can  be  carried  out  efficiently  without  planning.  The  discussion  here  does  not 
concern  one  set  of  policies  versus  another  set;  it  is  concerned  with  the  common  problems 
involved  in  any  type  of  planning  by  administrative  agencies. 


126  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

problems  in  the  various  substantive  fields  of  planning,  there  are  several 
aspects  of  planning  as  a  process  which  deserve  consideration.  Let  us  take 
these  up  in  their  proper  order. 

2.  THE  MACHINERY  FOR  PLANNING 

The  organizational  means  for  performing  the  planning  task  are  not 
easily  devised.  (Since  preparation  for  action  is  the  very  essence  of  adminis- 
tration, it  is  scarcely  possible  to  segregate  planning  as  a  single  act,  different 
from  all  other  work.  In  dividing  responsibilities,  an  administrator  cannot 
say,  "Planning  is  assigned  to  this  particular  branch."  Planning  in  one  form 
or  another  goes  on  at  all  levels  of  an  administrative  organization.  Almost 
the  entire  personnel  contributes  in  some  way  to  the  preparation  of  objectives 
and  programs.) 

(Yet,  considering  the  task  of  planning  as  a  phase  of  management,  admin- 
istrators have  often  found  it  convenient  and  desirable  to  establish  some  unit 
to  which  they  may  look  principally  as  their  adviser  on  planning.)  As  enter- 
prises get  larger,  a  need  is  felt  for  some  place  where  various  plans  can  be 
assembled,  reviewed,  fitted  together,  and  adjusted  to  one  another.  There 
is  also  a  need  for  some  particular  officer  or  unit  to  lay  out  the  common 
procedures—and  the  common  assumptions— upon  which  planning  is  to 
be  based. 

Federal  Improvisation.  Until  1934,  no  planning  agency  as  such  was 
attached  directly  to  the  President.  Planning  carried  on  within  the  govern- 
ment was  parceled  out  among  the  various  agencies.  In  general,  each  agency 
was  responsible  for  preparing  plans  related  to  its  work.  Sometimes  a  single 
department  was  given  broad  planning  responsibilities.  Thus,  the  National 
Defense  Act  as  amended  on  June  4,  1920,  provided  that  the  Assistant  Sec- 
retary of  War  should  assure  "adequate  provision  for  the  mobilization  of 
material  and  industrial  organizations  essential  to  wartime  needs"  (Sec.  5a). 
This  served  as  the  basis  for  building  up  what  amounted  to  a  national  plan- 
ning staff  on  economic  mobilization  within  the  War  Department. 

In  theory,  the  Cabinet  was  supposed  to  be  an  agency  for  debating  and 
advising  the  President  on  major  questions  of  policy.  From  such  evidence 
as  is  available  we  know  that  it  seldom  reached  such  lofty  stature.  It  was 
not  equipped  to  do  so.  Presidents  had  their  confidential  advisers,  who  were 
in  effect  their  planners.  Occasionally,  too,  special  committees  and  agencies 
were  created  to  propose  specific  programs.  One  of  these  was  the  Committee 
on  Economic  Security,  set  up  in  June,  1934,  whose  report  early  in  1935  pre- 
ceded the  enactment  of  our  social  security  legislation.  The  Federal  Em- 
ployment Stabilization  Board  was  created  by  act  of  Congress  in  1931  to 
plan  governmental  programs  for  promoting  employment  during  the  down- 
swing of  the  business  cycle.  This  board  was  abolished  in  1933.  The  Na- 
tional Commission  on  Law  Observance  and  Enforcement  was  another 
agency  specifically  created  by  act  of  Congress.  It  was  entrusted  in  1930 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  127 

with  the  task  of  reviewing  the  whole  system  of  federal  justice  and  planning 
improvements,  embodied  in  a  series  of  14  reports.  However,  no  continuing 
organization  was  provided  until  1934  to  meet  the  need  for  a  central  plan- 
ning agency  under  the  chief  executive. 

National  Resources  Planning  Board.  On  June  30,  1934,  by  Executive 
Order  No.  6777,  President  Roosevelt  established  the  National  Resources 
Board  composed  of  five  members  of  his  Cabinet,  the  Federal  Emergency 
Relief  Administrator,  and  three  prominent  citizens.  A  small  staff  was  pro- 
vided. This  new  agency  was  in  a  sense  a  continuation  of  a  planning  board 
created  by  the  Administrator  of  the  Federal  Emergency  Administration  for 
Public  Works.  The  new  board's  report  of  December  1,  1934,  stated  that  for 
the  "first  time  in  our  history"  exhaustive  studies  on  land  use,  water  use, 
minerals,  and  related  public  works  had  been  brought  together.  The  basis 
was  laid  for  a  "comprehensive  long-range  national  policy  for  the  conserva- 
tion and  development  of  our  fabulous  natural  resources."  In  1935,  the 
National  Resources  Board  was  reconstituted  as  the  National  Resources  Com- 
mittee with  virtually  the  same  membership. 

In  its  report  of  January  8,  1937,  the  President's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Management  declared: 

The  President  must  be  given  direct  control  over  and  be  charged  with 
immediate  responsibility  for  the  great  managerial  functions  of  the  gov- 
ernment which  affect  all  of  the  administrative  departments.  .  .  .  These 
functions  are  personnel  management,  fiscal  and  organizational  manage- 
ment, and  planning  management.  Within  these  three  groups  may  be 
comprehended  all  of  the  essential  elements  of  business  management. 

The  President's  Committee  recommended  that  a  National  Resources  Board, 
composed  of  five  members  without  salary  and  with  indefinite  terms,  be 
created  to  serve  as  a  central  planning  agency  under  the  chief  executive. 
After  the  passage  of  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  the  President  in  Reor- 
ganization Plan  No.  1  of  April  25,  1939,  provided  for  a  National  Resources 
Planning  Board.  The  Emergency  Relief  Appropriation  Act  of  1939  specified 
that  the  board  should  be  composed  of  three  persons  "from  widely  separated 
sections  of  the  United  States,"  appointed  by  the  President  with  the  approval 
of  the  Senate.  The  National  Resources  Planning  Board  came  to  an  end  when 
Congress,  in  passing  the  Independent  Offices  Appropriation  Act  of  1944, 
refused  to  include  any  funds  for  its  operations,  and  specifically  directed  that 
no  other  funds  were  to  be  made  available  for  its  continuance  by  the 
President. 

This  experience  with  a  central  planning  agency  in  the  federal  govern- 
ment underscored  the  difficulties  which  are  likely  to  beset  such  a  unit.  One 
essential  condition  for  the  successful  operation  of  a  planning  agency  is 
close  and  personal  relationship  with  the  chief  executive.  The  planners  must 
have  his  full  confidence  and  must  intimately  know  his  mind.  It  is  doubt- 
ful whether  any  board  can  ever  develop  such  relationships.  Especially 


128  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

would  this  be  impossible  when  a  board  is  torn  by  internal  persona] 
jealousies  or  disagreements.  Moreover,  the  planning  agency  must  also  be 
linked  to  operations  if  its  proposals  are  to  be  more  than  long-distance 
platitudes,  and  if  its  usefulness  is  to  be  apparent  to  legislators.  Then,  too 
the  planning  agency  must  be  used.  For  example,  although  the  National 
Resources  Board  was  set  up  by  the  President  as  early  as  June,  1934,  it 
played  no  part  in  planning  the  most  important  single  program  of  the  federa 
government  from  1933  to  1940— the  emergency  work  program  begun  b) 
the  Emergency  Relief  Appropriation  Act  of  April  8,  1935.  Indeed,  the  stor) 
of  planning  this  great  program  is  a  fascinating  example  of  how  a  govern 
ment  undertaking  is  prepared  and  put  into  operation.  It  has  been  told  ir 
full  elsewhere.7 

Office  of  War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion.  Before  the  Nationa 
Resources  Planning  Board  was  abolished,  a  new  type  of  planning  agenq 
was  already  in  process  of  development.  This  was  the  Office  of  War  Mobili 
zation,  which  was  created  by  Executive  Order  No.  9347  of  May  27,  1943 
Ostensibly  a  coordinating  device  for  the  many  wartime  programs  such  aj 
those  of  the  War  Production  Board,  Office  of  Price  Administration,  Wai 
Food  Administration,  National  War  Labor  Board,  and  the  War  and  Nav) 
Departments,  the  new  office  also  became  implicitly  a  central  planning 
agency.  It  was  under  its  auspices  that  Bernard  Baruch  and  John  Hancock 
submitted  their  Report  on  War  and  Postwar  Adjustment  Policies.  The 
preparation  of  legislation  on  disposal  of  surplus  property  and  on  the  settle 
ment  of  terminated  contracts  was  sponsored  by  this  office.  The  War  Mobili 
zation  and  Reconversion  Act  of  October  3,  1944,  placed  the  Office  of  Wai 
Mobilization  and  Reconversion  on  a  statutory — though  temporary — basi: 
and  entrusted  to  it  important  planning  responsibilities. 

In  several  respects  the  Office  of  War  Mobilization,  especially  in  it 
original  form,  suggested  a  device  superior  to  the  National  Resources  Plan 
ning  Board.  It  was  headed  by  a  single  individual  with  close  relationshif 
to  the  President.  It  was  concerned  with  immediate  programs  and  policie: 
as  well  as  with  the  preparation  of  future  programs.  There  was  little  doub 
about  its  contribution  to  war  and  postwar  administration,  even  thougl: 
not  all  of  its  potentialities  were  realized. 

New  Yorl(  City  Planning  Commission.  A  different  kind  of  planning 
organization  was  set  up  in  New  York  City  by  the  charter  adopted  ir 
1936.  Effective  on  January  1, 1928,  this  charter  provided  for  a  City  Planning 
Commission  of  seven  members,  one  of  whom  ex  officio  was  the  chief  engi 
neer  of  the  Board  of  Estimate.  The  other  six  members  were  to  be  appointee 
by  the  mayor  for  terms  of  eight  years.  Members  could  be  removed  by  th< 
mayor  only  on  proof  of  official  misconduct,  negligence,  conduct  discrediting 
the  office,  or  mental  or  physical  inability;  a  formal  hearing  was  requirec 

7  Sec  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  Millett,  John  D.  and  Ogdcn,  G.,  The  Administration  o. 
Federal  Wor\  Relief,  csp.  chs.  1-3,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1941. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  129 

before  removal.  Salaries  o£  the  members  were  not  to  be  reduced  during 
their  tenure.  The  recommendations  of  the  City  Planning  Commission  on 
zoning  regulations,  the  city  map,  and  land  subdivisions  became  effective 
unless  set  aside  by  a  three-fourths  majority  of  the  Board  of  Estimate. 
Finally,  the  commission  prepared  the  capital  expenditure  budget  of  the  city 
for  adoption  by  the  Board  of  Estimate  and  the  municipal  council.  The 
Board  of  Estimate  might  include  a  project  in  the  capital  budget  to  which 
the  City  Planning  Commission  was  opposed  only  by  a  three-fourths  majority. 
The  municipal  council  could  strike  out  a  capital  item  but  could  not  increase 
one  or  add  new  ones. 

Thus  in  several  ways  the  charter-makers  sought  to  provide  an  independ- 
ent type  of  planning  agency  for  city  affairs.  The  reasons  are  best 
summarized  in  the  words  of  the  framers  of  the  charter  themselves:8 

The  primary  purpose  of  such  a  commission  is  to  guide  and  to  influence 
the  city  in  its  development  and  future  growth.  The  growth  and  devel- 
opment of  a  modern  city  depend  upon  the  wisdom  and  foresight  with 
which  capital  improvements  are  undertaken  and  the  extent  to  which  the 
integrity  of  zoning  regulations  and  of  the  city  map  is  maintained.  Unfor- 
tunately, such  expenditures  too  often  have  been  undertaken  because  ot 
local  and  special  pressures  and  without  relation  to  the  interests  of  the 
city  as  a  whole.  Great  waste  has  resulted  and  a  species  of  logrolling  has 
developed  in  connection  with  measures  affecting  local  or  special  inter- 
ests. Such  evils  inevitably  occur  in  representative  government  when  sev- 
eral representatives  of  separate  constituencies  may  join  in  supporting 
measures  of  local  or  special  interest  affecting  their  several  constituencies 
or  followings.  But  such  evils  are  not  to  be  cured  by  abolishing  repre- 
sentative government,  or  by  substituting  one  representative  body  for 
another.  They  should  be  controlled  by  publicly  confronting  the  repre- 
sentatives with  the  interests  of  the  public  at  large.  Too  often  such  inter- 
est finds  no  advocacy  because  the  local  political  or  special  interest  is 
organized  and  the  general  interest  is  not. 

It  is  therefore  proposed  to  create  a  responsible,  independent  commis- 
sion concerned  with  the  welfare  of  the  whole  city,  to  advise  and  report 
upon  all  questions  affecting  the  growth  of  the  city,  including  the  expen- 
diture of  capital  funds,  changes  in  zoning,  and  changes  in  the  city 
map.  .  .  .  The  commission  will  report  its  conclusions  for  the  considera- 
tion and  action  of  the  Board  of  Estimate.  All  proposals  for  improve- 
ments or  for  changes  in  the  city  map  or  zoning  regulations  must  first 
be  referred  to  the  Planning  Commission.  If  approved,  the  Board  of 
Estimate  may  adopt  them  by  majority  vote;  if  not  approved,  twelve 
affirmative  votes  [three-fourths]  are  required.  Thus  the  Board  of  Esti- 
mate, consisting  of  the  elected  representatives  of  the  people,  is  given  the 
final  decision  as  to  the  projects  to  be  adopted,  but  the  function  of  plan- 
ning and  recommendation  is  given  to  a  nonpolitical,  full-time  body 
whose  decisions  cannot  be  lightly  overriden. 

Here  was  an  attempt  to  create  a  rather  independent  planning  commis- 

8  Preliminary  Report  and  Draft  of  Proposed  Charter  for  the  City  of  New  Yor%,  pp.  8-9, 
New  York:  New  York  City  Charter  Revision  Commission,  1936. 


130  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

sion.  Undoubtedly  this  effort  was  prompted  in  large  part  by  the  nature  of 
the  responsibility  entrusted  to  the  commission — planning  and  control  of 
land  use.  The  drafters  of  the  city  charter  sought  a  means  to  prevent  the 
many  abuses  in  land  use  which  had  previously  occurred.  But  the  approach 
proved  to  be  a  negative  one.  When  the  commission  sought  to  lay  out  a 
comprehensive  zoning  regulation,  the  political  authorities  of  the  city  were 
not  prepared  to  accept  the  program  and  fundamental  modifications  were 
necessary.9  Thus  need  for  political  leadership  in  planning  was  well  demon- 
strated. The  independent  commission  was  not  as  independent  in  accom- 
plishing its  mission  as  might  have  been  expected. 

Departmental  Planning  Units.  Within  the  main  agencies  of  the  federal 
government,  several  department  heads  have  found  a  need  for  at  least  an 
individual  adviser  to  help  in  the  preparation  of  departmental  plans.10  In 
some  departments  yet  another  step  has  been  taken — the  establishment  of  a 
planning  office.  If  a  department  is  to  play  its  role  as  an  integrating  force 
for  the  operating  establishments  composing  it,  strong  central  planning 
machinery  is  necessary.  Secretary  Elihu  Root  perceived  this  need  for  the 
War  Department  after  the  Spanish-American  War.  His  efforts  led  to  the 
creation  of  the  position  of  Chief  of  Staff  and  the  establishment  of  the  Gen- 
eral Staff  in  1903.  More  recently  the  Department  of  Agriculture  took  a 
similar  step  by  making  its  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics  a  central 
planning  unit.11 

There  are  a  number  of  organizational  problems  connected  with  plan- 
ning. Shall  the  planning  agency  be  headed  by  a  single  individual  or  a 
board?  Shall  the  planning  agency  be  a  single  adviser  or  a  fairly  sizable 
office?  Shall  it  be  closely  tied  to  the  chief  executive  or  department  head, 
or  shall  it  be  given  some  kind  of  protected  status  to  encourage  what  has 
been  called  an  independent  point  of  view?  The  answers  which  modern 
proponents  of  administrative  management  would  give  are  clear.  Leader- 
ship in  planning  is  a  responsibility  of  the  chief  executive  or  department 
head.  The  administrator  needs  planning  assistance  which  can  best  be  af- 
forded by  a  single  individual  as  head  of  an  adequate  planning  unit.  Only 
in  this  way  can  planning  contribute  its  full  potentialities  to  efficient 
administration. 

3.  PLANNING  VERSUS  OPERATIONS 

'  Opportunities  for  Conflict.    Forty  years  ago,  Elihu  Root  spoke  of  the 
"eternal  issue  of  planning  versus  administration."   The  question  is  indeed 

9  Sec  Tugwell,  R.  G.,  "Implementing  the  General  Interest,"  Public  Administration  Review, 
1940,  Vol.  1,  p.  32  ff. 

^See  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.  and  Millctt,  John  D.,  Federal  Administrators,  ch.  4,  New 
York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1939. 

^Gaus,  John  M.  and  Wolcott,  Leon  O.,  Public  Administration  and  the  Department  of 
Agriculture,  p.  311,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1940.  The  most  comprehensive 
study  of  the  military  prototype  is  Nelson,  Otto  L.,  National  Security  and  the  General  Staff, 
Washington:  Infantry  Journal  Press,  1946. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  131 

eternal;  no  ready  solution  is  available  today  any  more  than  four  decades 
ago.  In  its  essence,  the  problem  has  two  phases.  One  is  the  relationship 
of  planning  to  operations,  or  of  planners  to  administrators.  The  other  is 
the  relationship  of  plans  to  action. 

There  is  apt  to  develop  in  any  agency  the  attitude  among  subordinate 
operating  units  that  the  staff  personnel  at  superior  levels  spends  its  time 
developing  programs  which  prove  impractical  in  execution.  The  complaint 
may  in  reality  be  based  on  failure  of  consultation  and  explanation.  Of  one 
thing  there  is  little  doubt;  all  plans  must  be  closely  geared  to  operations. 
They  must  be  realizable;  and  that  means  capable  of  execution  by  the  oper- 
ating units.  It  is  a  matter  of  personal  relations  as  well  as  of  effective 
management  for  planning  staffs  to  maintain  continuing  contact  with 
operating  personnel — to  know  their  problems,  seek  their  advice,  and  review 
proposed  programs  prior  to  action. 

Tasf(  of  Progressive  Management.  It  is  a  fairly  good  rule,  and  one  that 
should  be  generally  observed  in  administrative  practice,  for  a  central  plan- 
ning agency  in  municipal,  state,  or  federal  government,  or  even  in  a  large 
department,  to  do  as  little  direct  planning  as  possible.  The  central  unit 
should  stimulate  and  review;  it  should  experiment  with  new  techniques 
and  devices;  it  should  cover  subjects  not  within  the  scope  of  subordinate 
units.  For  other  activities,  there  are  reasons  of  expediency  and  efficiency 
which  urge  that  subordinate  operating  agencies  or  units  be  encouraged  tc 
do  the  bulk  of  necessary  planning.  It  is  an  indication  of  poor  management 
when  cleavages  develop  between  planning  staffs  and  operating  officials. 

To  be  sure,  planners  are  expected  to  be  imaginative,  to  project  bold 
courses  of  action,  to  weigh  all  possible  alternatives.  Operating  officials  may 
have  their  horizons  more  narrowly  limited  to  their  immediate  concerns 
Frequently  they  may  let  reasons  of  convenience  sway  them  against  a  pro- 
posed line  of  action  because  it  may  mean  more  work  for  them.  These 
are  dangers  that  must  be  guarded  against.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  vitall) 
important  that  all  operating  obstacles  be  clearly  understood  before  a  parti 
cular  policy  or  program  is  adopted.  Such  difficulties  can  be  most  readilj 
forecast  by  those  having  operating  responsibilities.  Thus  a  balance  musi 
always  be  sought  between  broadly  conceived  goals  and  the  practical  limita 
tions  of  ways  and  means.  This  is  just  another  way  of  saying  that  th( 
gulf  between  planning  and  operations  must  be  bridged  by  progressiv< 
management. 

Planners  as  Administrators.  The  other  phase  of  the  issue  between  plan 
ning  and  performance  concerns  the  execution  of  well-laid  plans.  Specifi 
cally,  should  planners  become  the  administrators  of  their  plans  whei 
adopted?  Here  again  no  categorical  answer  is  possible.  If  there  is  such  ; 
thing  as  an  identifiable  planning  mentality,  it  may  well  be  that  its  necessar 
characteristics  are  different  from  those  required  to  make  a  successfu 
administrator.  On  the  other  hand,  we  do  observe  in  certain  agencies  th< 


132  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

practice  of  assigning  to  a  group  of  men  the  developing  task  of  long-range 
plans  for  certain  operations.  Later,  as  the  time  approaches  for  action,  the 
same  people  are  assigned  to  supervise  execution.  Under  appropriate  condi- 
tions, the  practice  may  work  satisfactorily.  The  planners  thus  become 
the  administrative  supervisors. 

Yet,  when  supervisory  authority  is  lodged  in  the  same  staff  agency  that 
exercises  planning  responsibilities,  the  planning  function  may  suffer.  In 
1942,  before  he  became  Deputy  Chief  of  Staff  of  the  Army,  General  Mc- 
Narney  told  a  Senate  committee  that  the  General  Staff  of  the  War  De- 
partment had  taken  on  so  many  administrative  duties  that  its  planning 
work  had  suffered  in  consequence.12  The  answer  in  this  case  was  to  set 
up  three  great  commands  to  exercise  virtually  all  War  Department  functions 
i  in  the  United  States  and  so  free  the  General  Staff  of  its  burdensome  coor- 
dinating job.  There  is  always  a  danger  that  a  planning  unit  may  find  ad- 
Ipnistrative  supervision  of  day-to-day  work  more  tangible  and  more  inter- 
esting than  planning.  This  is  especially  apt  to  happen  if  there  is  no  other 
agency  for  exercising  the  necessary  measure  of  supervision.  Certain  it  is 
that  ability  as  a  planner  is  not  sure  proof  of  administrative  capacity.  The 
combination  of  the  two  tasks  in  the  same  individual  or  agency  is  not  a 
foolproof  method  of  uniting  planning  and  operations. 

Practical  Test  of  Planning.  Plans  should  be  intended  for  action.  When 
approved,  and  when  the  necessary  funds  are  made  available,  a  set  of  plans 
must  next  be  carried  out.  Action  accordingly  follows  after  the  planning. 
Much  of  the  success  in  operation  depends  upon  the  thoroughness  of  the 
plans.  And  purposeful  administrative  activity  depends  upon  advance  prep- 
aration. There  is  no  inherent  conflict  between  planning  and  operations. 
The  two  are  inexorably  entwined. 

David  Lilienthal,  chairman  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  men- 
tions with  some  pride  that  nowhere  on  its  organization  chart  will  the 
student  find  a  Department  of  Social  Planning,  and  that  there  is  no  TVA 
"plan."13  Yet  he  admits  that  TVA  is  a  planning  agency.  "The  TVA  idea 
of  planning  sees  action  and  planning  not  as  things  separate  and  apart  but 
as  one  single  and  continuous  process."14  Mr.  Lilienthal  goes  on  to  argue 
that  the  development  of  a  region  is  a  course  of  action.  He  acknowledges 
that  TVA  has  made  many  plans,  but  he  also  emphasizes  the  authority's 
responsibility  for  action  in  the  following  words: 

In  the  TVA  the  merging  of  planning  and  responsibility  for  the  carry- 
ing out  of  those  plans  forces  our  technicians  to  make  them  a  part  of  the 
main  stream  of  living  in  the  region  or  community;  this  it  is  that  breathes 
into  plans  the  breath  of  life.  For  in  the  Tennessee  Valley  the  expert 
cannot  escape  from  the  consequences  of  his  planning,  as  he  can  and 

12  Senate  Committee  on  Military  Affairs,  Hearings  on  a  Bill  to  Establish  a  Department  of 
Defense  Coordination  and  Control,  p.  13,  76th  Cong.,  2nd  Sess.,  March  6,  1942. 

*3  Lilienthal,  David  E.,  TV  A— Democracy  on  the  March,  p.  192,  New  York:  Harper,  1944. 
U  MM/.,  p.  199. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  133 

usually  does  where  it  is  divorced  from  execution.  This  has  a  profound 
effect  on  the  experts  themselves.  Where  planning  is  conceived  of  in 
this  way,  the  necessity  that  experts  should  be  close  to  the  problems  with 
which  they  are  dealing  is  evident.115 

Planning  Through  Action  Agencies.  Mr.  Lilienthal  is  not  arguing 
against  planning.  Rather,  he  is  emphasizing  that  planning  should  be  done 
by  action  agencies  or  action  units.  His  position  is  a  strong  one.  His 
case  can  be  applied  to  a  large  department  as  well  as  to  TVA  in  its  rela- 
tions to  the  government  as  a  whole.  There  is  good  reason  indeed  why  the 
primary  responsibility  for  the  preparation  of  plans  should  be  placed  upon 
operating  officials.  But  usually  they  will  need  to  have  specially  designated 
personnel  to  develop  the  plans.  And  all  the  plans  must  be  put  together  as 
a  whole. 

Although  Mr.  Lilienthal  does  not  say  so,  we  may  presume  that  the  TVA 
board  and  its  general  manager  found  that  they  themselves  could  put  the 
plans  of  operating  officials  together.  Hence  there  was  no  need  for  central 
staff  planners  in  TVA.  Nor  does  Mr.  Lilienthal  deny  that  TVA  plans 
must  in  the  long  run  be  made  to  harmonize  with  the  plans  of  the  federal 
government  as  a  whole.  However,  it  is  advantageous  and  desirable  to 
leave  a  maximum  measure  of  planning  responsibility  to  operating  agencies 
or  units,  and  to  encourage  close  relationships  between  planning  specialists 
and  those  who  will  direct  the  execution  of  plans. 

4.  THE  REQUIREMENTS  OF  PLANNING 

Long-Range  Versus  Short-Range  Planning.  The  question  of  whether  to 
place  emphasis  upon  long-range  or  short-range  planning  is  very  similar  to 
the  issue  of  the  relation  of  planning  to  operations.  Students  of  administra- 
tion have  noticed  a  tendency  in  many  agencies  to  concentrate  attention 
upon  matters  of  short-range  concern,  to  the  exclusion  of  any  interest  in 
longer-range  goals.  No  doubt  this  practice  reflects  in  part  the  interest  of 
administrative  officials  in  action;  they  want  to  see  something  happen — and 
soon.  It  also  discloses  a  natural  responsiveness  to  legislative  attitudes; 
lawmakers  do  not  look  with  fond  eyes  on  long-range  planning  by  the 
executive  branch.  Furthermore,  it  reveals  that  the  postponement  of  thought 
about  long-range  goals  may  often  result  from  the  pressures  of  the  current 
job. 

This  kind  of  tendency  can  arise  even  in  a  planning  agency.  For  exam- 
ple, the  New  York  City  Planning  Commission  had  a  Division  of  Master 
Plan  with  two  main  duties:  first,  long-range  concern  with  the  future  physi- 
cal improvement  of  the  city;  second,  the  current  job  of  preparing  reports 
on  proposed  building  sites  for  immediate  construction,  reviewing  assessable 
improvements,  and  commenting  on  the  proposed  sale  of  city  properties. 
The  staff  of  the  division  was  not  large  enough  to  permit  adequate  efforts 

15 /£«/.,  p.  201  (by  permission  of  the  publisher). 


134  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

on  both  jobs.  As  a  result,  the  current  work  was  done,  and  the  long-range 
planning  neglected.  The  eventual  solution  in  this  case  was  to  take  on  one 
additional  engineer  to  routinize  the  current  work  by  devising  "stock"  com- 
ments and  forms,  and  to  set  up  a  separate  section  to  concentrate  upon  the 
long-range  master  plan.  Isolation  of  the  long-range  planners  was  avoided 
by  short,  informal  staff  conferences  held  each  day  within  the  division.  This 
change  evidently  achieved  the  desired  results.16 

Ideally,  there  should  be  no  conflict  between  short-run  and  long-run 
planning.  The  two  again  are  interrelated.  Short-run  plans  must  be  part 
of  a  long-range  objective,  if  the  work  when  accomplished  is  to  have  any 
meaning.  A  new,  wide  street  laid  out  to  the  edge  of  a  city,  built  to  haul 
much  traffic,  will  be  of  little  use  unless  it  is  connected  with  main  roads  and 
unless  the  city  grows  in  that  direction.  A  plan  for  the  expansion  of  a 
manufacturing  plant  will  be  of  little  value  unless  there  is  a  sustained 
market  demand  for  the  product  when  made.  There  is  no  point  in  develop- 
ing harbor  facilities  unless  there  is  also  a  longer-range  plan  for  moving 
increased  tonnage  through  the  port. 

At  the  same  time,  the  determination  of  short-run  programs  is  the 
occasion  for  reviewing  the  adequacy  of  long-range  plans  and  for  modify- 
ing them  to  meet  current  conditions.  The  desirable  connection  is  exempli- 
fied in  current  capital-budgeting  practices  in  our  more  advanced  cities. 
The  usual  practice  is  to  adopt  each  year  an  annual  program  of  capital  im- 
provements, but  simultaneously  to  furnish  a  plan  for  desirable  improve- 
ments over  the  next  five  years.  Each  year  a  current  program  is  presented, 
and  another  year  added  to  the  long-run  plan.  The  National  Resources 
Planning  Board  followed  the  same  practice  from  1940  to  1942  in  presenting 
a  six-year  program  of  construction  to  be  undertaken  or  financed  by  the 
federal  government.  Generally  speaking,  it  is  the  task  of  competent  manage- 
ment to  make  certain  that  a  proper  balance  is  maintained  between  short-run 
and  long-run  planning. 

Planning  Personnel.  The  president  of  a  large  company  once  remarked 
that  there  are  only  a  few  men  in  any  organization  to  whom  planning  re- 
sponsibilities can  be  entrusted.  Most  people,  he  observed,  are  frightened 
when  asked  to  look  ahead  and  prepare  for  future  activities.  In  other  words, 
this  executive  was  convinced  that  there  was  a  special  type  of  personnel  best 
suited  for  planning. 

Unquestionably,  there  are  certain  attributes  which  are  desirable  in  a 
planner.  He  must  be  imaginative,  broad-visioned,  willing  to  explore  new 
and  unusual  conceptions,  free  from  prejudice  about  basic  goals.  He  must 
be  objective,  thorough,  flexible.  He  should  be  willing  to  canvass  alterna- 
tives and  forecast  probable  results  without  extravagant  optimism  or  pessim- 

16  See  Boemi,  A.  Andrew,  "Organization  o£  a  City  Planning  Department  for  Current  and 
Long-Term  Activities,"  Report  No.  21,  Case  Reports  in  Public  Administration,  Vol.  I,  Chicago: 
Public  Administration  Service,  1940. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  135 

ism.  He  must  have  technical  competence  in  his  field  of  work.  He  must 
not  be  afraid  of  details.  He  must  have  a  mind  which  quickly  perceives 
interrelationships  between  various  programs  of  action,  and  fits  pieces  to- 
gether into  a  harmonious  whole.  He  must  be  able  to  get  along  well  with 
others  throughout  the  organization.  In  other  words,  he  must  be  a  good 
staff  officer.  All  these  characteristics  are  desirable  in  planning  personnel. 

To  be  sure,  it  is  easier  to  state  these  general  qualifications  than  it  is  to 
measure  them.  In  large  part,  the  personality  traits  just  described  can  only 
be  judged  subjectively.  A  chief  executive  or  administrator  will  have  to 
decide  which  prospective  candidates  possess  the  desired  combination  of 
characteristics  for  staff  leadership  in  planning.  This  is  merely  a  way  of 
saying  that  few  selections  by  an  administrator  are  more  important  to  the 
success  of  his  enterprise  than  the  designation  of  his  chief  planner.  It  is  a 
vital  choice,  and  not  one  to  be  made  hastily  or  casually. 

Because  planning  is  so  intimately  allied  with  questions  of  major  policy 
and  decision,  it  is  frequently  believed  that  the  planners  must  necessarily 
be  political  officers.  Presidents  and  department  heads  are  usually  expected 
to  draw  their  close  advisers  from  among  their  personal  confidants  or  politi- 
cal associates.  This  practice  has  its  advantages.  It  brings  new  backgrounds 
and  points  of  view  into  the  public  service.  It  often  helps  to  ensure  loyalty 
and  full  trust  between  the  administrator  and  his  advisers. 

The  defects  in  this  practice,  however,  are  equally  obvious.  The  new- 
comer must  take  a  long  period  to  become  fully  acquainted  with  the  agency 
where  he  is  assigned.  He  must  learn  the  full  impact  of  present  programs 
and  the  probable  repercussions  of  change.  More  than  this,  he  must  be  able 
to  command  positive  reactions  all  the  way  down  the  administrative  hier- 
archy. He  has  to  be  very  sure  of  himself  and  well  versed  in  administrative 
practices  to  achieve  so  much. 

If  the  administrator  seeks  his  planning  advisers  from  within  the  ranks 
of  the  permanent  civil  service,  he  will  gain  the  advantage  of  having  indi- 
viduals with  a  full  knowledge  of  personalities,  programs,  and  problems 
peculiar  to  the  particular  department.  Today,  in  the  federal  government 
and  in  most  states,  our  departments  are  so  large  that  many  different  points 
of  view  and  types  of  individuals  are  to  be  found  within  them.  It  is  likely 
that  an  agency  head  can  find,  without  too  much  difficulty,  the  civil  servant 
upon  whom  he  will  be  willing  to  rely  heavily  as  a  planning  adviser. 

Yet  if  a  civil  servant  is  to  fill  such  a  position,  he  must  inevitably  associate 
himself  with  the  policies  of  his  chief.  When  those  policies  are  changed 
by  a  successor,  the  planner  is  likely  to  go  too.  Must  the  price  for  direction 
of  planning  activities  be  eventual  severance  from  the  public  service?  It 
would  seem  desirable  to  develop  some  arrangement  whereby  civil  servants 
might  hold  higher  posts  like  this  under  one  political  leadership  and  in  case 
of  change  be  returned  to  their  earlier  duties  or  other  responsibilities.  For 
instance,  it  was  found  a  few  years  ago  that  the  Post  Office  Department  was 


136  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

largely  managed  by  the  deputy  assistant  postmasters  general  and  the  chief 
inspectors,  who  were  drawn  from  the  ranks  of  the  department  but  who 
tended  to  shift  with  changes  in  departmental  leadership.17  When  replaced, 
a  deputy  assistant  postmaster  general  went  back  to  his  previous  position. 
While  this  arrangement  had  its  defects,  it  might  serve  as  a  precedent  for 
application  to  planning  personnel. 

Another  question  is  whether  special  efforts  should  be  made  through 
civil  service  procedures  to  recruit  specialized  personnel  specifically  for  staff 
work  in  planning  agencies.  The  answer  would  appear  to  depend  upon  the 
characteristics  of  individual  agencies.  If  the  tendency  for  public  agencies 
to  seek  young  technicians  in  many  different  fields  for  operating  and  man- 
agement jobs  should  continue,  there  would  be  no  reason  to  advocate  any 
special  approach  for  the  recruitment  of  planning  personnel.  The  scope  of 
the  professions  now  recognized  in  the  merit  system  should  be  sufficient  to 
meet  planning  needs.  We  must  remember  that  planning  is  a  management 
function;  it  is  a  technique,  a  method,  an  attitude.  It  is  not  some  special 
body  of  knowledge.  Planning  is  performed  as  a  phase  of  operations  in 
various  fields.  We  should  continue  to  seek  general  professional  competence 
first,  and  then  look  for  the  individual  with  the  peculiar  personal  qualifi- 
cations and  inclinations  which  make  him  suitable  for  the  planning  staff 
of  an  agency. 

Planning  Techniques.  Research  and  planning  are  not  synonymous; 
rather,  the  two  are  complementary.  Careful  collection  of  all  available  in- 
formation and  analysis  of  past  trends  usually  precedes  the  formulation  of 
future  action.  Planning  is  this  second  step — the  formulation  of  future 
action  to  attain  desirable  ends. 

One  method  of  procedure  in  planning  is  to  begin  with  certain  standards 
of  attainment  in  a  particular  field.  If  a  standard  is  available,  it  may  be  used 
as  a  measuring  rod  in  determining  what  we  have  as  contrasted  with  what 
is  desirable.  The  difference,  or  "gap,"  is  an  indication  of  what  we  have  to 
do.  The  final  step  is  to  lay  out  a  program  for  achieving  the  desired  stand- 
ard. Another  way  of  stating  the  same  procedure  is:  (1)  to  determine  the 
objectives;  (2)  to  measure  the  distance  between  the  present  status  and  the 
objectives;  (3)  to  determine  the  program  for  realizing  the  objectives. 

In  its  last  year,  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board  experimented 
with  the  latter  approach  in  several  different  fields.  For  instance,  the  stand- 
ard of  nutritional  need  was  used  as  a  guide  to  land-use  planning  in  agri- 
culture. The  objective  was  an  American  population  provided  with  an 
adequate  and  properly  balanced  diet.  The  science  of  nutrition  had  reached 
a  point  where  it  could  say  with  precision  what  an  adequate  and  balanced 
diet  is.  Diet  needs  per  individual  for  different  types  of  food,  multiplied 
by  total  population,  gave  the  objective  in  quantitative  terms.  This  objec- 

17  See  Macmahon  and  Millctt,  op.  cit.  in  note  10,  p.  36. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  137 

tive  in  turn  was  translated  into  acreage  requirements.  Required  acreage 
compared  with  existing  acreage  indicated  broadly  the  "gap"  to  be  bridged 
in  obtaining  agricultural  production  for  an  adequate  food  consumption. 

The  same  approach  was  used  for  public  libraries.  With  the  assistance 
of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board,  the  American  Library  Associa- 
tion undertook  to  formulate  standards  for  public  libraries.18  Comparison 
of  existing  library  service  with  these  standards  supplied  a  basis  for  prepara- 
tion of  a  program  to  realize  the  standards. 

The  principal  mechanism  of  urban  land-use  planning  has  long  been 
the  master  plan,  which  is  designed  to  present  the  current  conception  of 
long-run  city  development.  More  specifically,  it  presents  an  estimate  of 
needed  capital  improvements.  This  means,  of  course,  laying  out  the  ex- 
pected population  growth  and  shifts  within  a  city,  and  then  providing  the 
facilities  to  meet  the  anticipated  needs.  It  implies  some  standard  for  in- 
dicating needs  in  schools,  parks,  fire  houses,  streets,  sewers,  water  mains, 
and  all  other  municipal  facilities.19  The  master  plan  also  shows  all  existing 
public  structures.  In  short,  it  is  expected  to  provide  the  basic  data  for  a 
capital-improvement  budget  for  a  city.  Unfortunately,  few  cities  in  the 
United  States  have  ever  developed  even  a  good  approximation  of  a  master 
plan.  Much  improvisation  still  passes  as  city  planning. 

For  many  years  the  United  States  Forest  Service  has  used  a  forest  man- 
agement plan  as  its  basic  planning  program.  Under  this  program,  each 
supervisor  of  a  forest  keeps  an  up-to-date  local  forest-management  plan  for 
his  area.  This  plan  divides  a  forest  into  working  circles.  For  each  circle 
there  are  data  about  topography,  number  of  trees,  and  rate  of  growth. 
The  plan  then  indicates  the  silvicultural  system  or  the  genetics  and  ecology 
of  tree  growth,  the  timber  yield,  the  policy  on  timber  sales,  the  selection 
of  areas  to  be  cut,  and  the  annual  permissible  cut.  The  forest  management 
plan  became  the  basis  in  turn  for  a  regional  management  plan,  which  was 
incorporated  into  a  national  management  plan.  Thus  the  Forest  Service  de- 
veloped a  program  for  its  work  in  forestry  operation. 

There  are  various  techniques  for  planning,  but  they  have  in  common 
the  collection  of  relevant  data  on  which  to  build  a  program  for  realizing 
specified  objectives.  Whatever  techniques  are  employed,  planning  must 
look  forward;  it  must  propose  desirable  action.  The  more  concrete  and 
detailed  the  program,  the  better  has  been  the  planning.  And  this  means 
inevitably  more  efficient  administration.  Studies  in  themselves  are  not 
plans.  The  planning  job  is  not  done  until  specific  and  detailed  programs 
have  been  worked  out.  The  plans  should  be  in  such  condition  that  operat- 
ing officials  could  begin  immediately  to  carry  them  out. 

18  Sec  Postwar  Standards  for  Public  Libraries,  Chicago:  American  Library  Association,  1943. 

10  See,  for  example,  "Preliminary  Report  of  the  Committee  on  Park  and  Recreation 
Standards,"  in  Planning,  1943,  p.  106  ff.t  Chicago:  American  Society  of  Planning  Officials, 
1943. 


138  PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

Public  Relations  of  Planning.  The  final  problem  of  planning  is  getting 
the  program  across.  As  we  saw,  planning  is  a  responsibility  of  the  top 
administrator.  It  is  his  duty  to  present  the  program  to  the  chief  executive 
and  to  the  legislature.  He  is  the  advocate.  The  technicians  who  may  have 
prepared  the  data  are  only  members  of  his  staff. 

Yet  the  administrator  must  naturally  be  concerned  about  the  public  re- 
percussions of  a  program  he  accepts.  This  has  led  many  planners  to  feel 
that  they  must  themselves  cultivate  outside  sources  of  support.  Certainly 
it  may  be  contended  that  planners  should  consult  many  different  groups 
in  framing  proposals.  A  sense  of  participation  may  encourage  some  in- 
dividuals and  groups  to  endorse  later  plans.  There  is  much  room  in  the 
planning  process  for  advisory  committees  as  well  as  for  extensive  consul- 
tation with  citizen  and  interest  groups. 

Some  chief  planners  have  found  it  desirable  that  they  themselves  serve 
as  intermediaries  between  their  technical  staffs  and  the  public.  They  have 
feared  that  their  "experts"  might  frighten  or  upset  the  average  citizen  or 
legislator.  So  they  have  been  the  filters  for  presentation  of  data  and  pro- 
posals to  the  outside.  There  is  much  to  say  for  this  practice.  Chief  planners 
must  also  supply  the  links  between  their  technicians  and  the  political  head 
of  the  agency — a  task  requiring  considerable  skill  in  communication  and 
interpretation. 

Planning,  viewed  from  the  angle  of  its  concrete  end-product,  leads  to 
a  selling  job.  The  planning  personnel  must  be  prepared  to  help  in  the 
process  of  sale.  The  burden  of  getting  programs  accepted  cannot  be  left 
solely  to  the  responsible  political  chief.  While  the  planner  must  make  it 
clear  that  he  is  not  the  official  responsible  for  determining  policy,  he  must 
assist  in  showing  the  grounds  which  make  a  program  desirable.  It  follows 
that  for  many  reasons  planners,  because  they  are  planners,  cannot  afford 
to  ignore  the  public-relations  problems  inherent  in  their  job. 

Summary.  Preparation  for  action  is  a  vital — indeed  an  indispensable — 
part  of  administration.  It  is  the  first  responsibility  of  management.  Many 
other  phases  of  management  must  flow  in  turn  from  planning.  Particu- 
larly, budgeting  is  very  closely  tied  to  planning,  for  the  budget  is  merely  the 
fiscal  expression  of  work  plans.20  Organizational  planning  follows  the 
tasks  laid  out  for  an  agency.  Planning  covers  many  fields — conservation  of 
natural  resources,  land  use,  public  works,  economic  development.  An  ad- 
ministrator, to  perform  his  planning  responsibility,  must  have  the  necessary 
staff  whose  head  works  in  close  personal  relationship  with  him.  Planners  at 
the  higher  levels  in  the  administrative  hierarchy  have  a  management  job 
to  do.  They  have  to  stimulate  planning  by  other  staff  and  operating  agen- 
cies or  units,  in  order  to  ensure  that  plans  are  in  balance,  that  synthesis  has 
been  achieved,  and  that  all  aspects  have  been  fully  considered.  Planners 


20  See  Walker,  Robert  A.,  "The  Relation  of  Budgeting  to  Program  Planning,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  97  ff. 


PLANNING  AND  ADMINISTRATION  139 

must  prepare  plans  themselves  in  those  fields  where  there  is  no  operating 
agency.  Planning  and  operations  should  not  be  regarded  as  being  antag- 
onistic. Rather,  they  should  be  considered  as  interlocking  and  as  repre- 
senting succeeding  phases  of  administrative  activity.  So  also  short-range 
plans  should  be  carefully  geared  to  long-range  objectives.  Planning  tech- 
niques should  be  designed  to  lay  out  work  programs  for  meeting  deter- 
mined goals.  Capital  budgets  and  current  operating  budgets  should  be 
phases  of  these  techniques. 

Personnel  engaged  in  planning  should  be  carefully  selected  for  technical 
competence  and  ability  to  think  ahead  in  original  projections.  Planning 
requires  careful  definition  of  objectives,  wherever  possible  in  quantitative 
terms,  on  the  basis  of  an  inventory  of  present  status  and  resources  and  aim- 
ing at  a  program  for  realizing  these  objectives.  Consultation  with  various 
interested  groups  is  an  essential  part  of  this  process.  Well-defined  object- 
ives—a clear  comprehension  of  goals— means  purposeful  administration 
accompanied  by  the  least  possible  loss  in  wasted  effort. 


CHAPTER 

7 

Working  Concepts  of  Organization 

1.  THE  ARCHITECTURE  OF  ORGANIZATION 

Terminology.  Organization  is  the  method  of  dividing  up  work.  It 
rests  upon  two  basic  conditions.  First,  organization  implies  that  there  is 
a  job  to  be  done.  Second,  division  of  work  becomes  necessary  only  when 
a  number  of  individuals  are  involved  in  accomplishing  a  particular  job. 
In  a  relatively  simple  situation,  organization  may  be  informal  and  even 
implicit.  It  may  depend  upon  tradition  or  habit.  As  the  job  becomes  larger, 
as  the  purpose  becomes  more  complex,  as  the  number  of  people  performing 
the  job  increases,  organization  tends  to  be  more  exactly  defined. 

When  we  use  the  word  "organization,"  we  shall  have  in  mind  a  rather 
restricted  and  particular  meaning.  We  are  not  concerned  with  the  organi- 
zation of  government  as  a  federal  republic,  or  with  its  legislative,  executive 
and  judicial  branches;  here  we  are  not  dealing  with  basic  theories  about 
political  structure.  Nor  are  we  touching  upon  the  organization  of  society 
into  family  units,  social  groups,  or  economic  associations.  Our  concern 
now  is  with  specific  work  undertaken  by  government,  whether  federal,  state, 
or  local.  Many  of  the  considerations  to  which  we  have  to  pay  attention 
hence  are  also  applicable  to  business  enterprise,  and  likewise  to  undertakings 
such  as  hospitals  and  schools.  Organization,  for  our  present  purposes, 
refers  to  the  structure  developed  for  carrying  out  the  tasks  entrusted 
to  the  chief  executive  and  his  administrative  subordinates  in  government. 

It  is  customary  to  point  out  that  organization  has  grown  in  importance 
with  the  increasing  specialization  of  individuals.  Division  of  labor,  for 
example,  was  a  basic  factor  in  industrialization.  We  found  that  productive 
output  increased  with  specialization.  But  specialization  required  organi- 
zation, since  all  effort  must  add  up  to  the  desired  output.  We  do  not  get 
a  suit  of  clothes  unless  the  cutters  use  a  suit  pattern  in  cutting  the  cloth 
and  the  sewers  know  the  particular  parts  to  sew  and  in  what  order.  If  all 
the  workers  sewed  sleeves,  there  would  be  no  suit.  So  we  must  have 
workers  who  sew  sleeves,  and  others  who  sew  coat  seams,  and  still  others 

140 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  141 

who  sew  the  trousers.  The  work  of  each  must  be  thus  systematically  al- 
located in  order  to  achieve  the  desired  product. 

Over  the  years  we  have  developed  a  number  of  definite  conceptions 
of  the  ways  in  which  work  can  and  should  be  divided.  To  be  sure,  we  are 
a  long  way  yet  from  final  and  conclusive  answers  to  all  organizational 
questions.  There  are  differences  of  opinion  about  many  particular  phases 
of  organization.  There  is  ample  room  for  experimentation  in  organizational 
relations.  Administrative  structure  is  not  static.  New  ideas  bring  new 
trends  in  organization.  |  Yet  there  remain  certain  fundamental  concepts  in 
organization  which  all  should  understand.  Phrases  like  "bases  of  organiza- 
tion," "unity  of  command,"  "hierarchy,"  "decentralization,"  "staff  and 
line,"  and  "span  of  control"  have  rather  definite  meanings,  j  It  will  prove 
useful  in  the  present  chapter  to  review  briefly  these  workmg  concepts  of 
organization. 

Bases  of  Organization.  Students  of  organization  usually  recognize  four 
different  bases  for  organizations,  in  the  sense  of  different  methods  of  dividing 
up  a  job.  These  are:  function  or  purpose,  process  or  profession,  clientele  or 
commodity,  and  area. 

Function  or  purpose  is  fairly  easy  to  define.  Education  of  children 
through  a  public  school  system  is  a  particular  function  or  purpose  which 
an  agency  may  be  established  to  perform.  The  conduct  of  foreign  relations, 
the  collection  of  taxes,  the  operation  of  a  navy,  the  provision  of  public 
assistance  to  the  destitute,  the  disposal  of  garbage  and  refuse— all  of  these 
are  functional  definitions  of  administrative  jobs.  Within  a  particular 
field,  too,  such  as  public  welfare  or  social  security,  the  component  parts  of 
governmental  activity  may  be  divided  functionally,  as  between  unem- 
ployment insurance  and  what  we  used  to  call  relief.  On  an  assembly  line, 
in  much  the  same  way,  the  job  of  putting  together  an  automobile  is  broken 
up  into  various  functions.  The  wheels  and  then  the  engine  are  attached  to 
the  chassis,  the  body  and  fenders  are  added  later,  and  finally  the  completed 
automobile  rolls  from  the  assembly  line.  Each  man  along  the  line  has 
performed  a  particular  function,  such  as  fastening  on  a  wheel  or  connecting 
a  driveshaft. 

Functional  division  of  duties  or  division  by  purpose  is  perhaps  the  most 
common  of  all  methods  of  promoting  specialization.  There  are  many  who 
maintain  that  it  is  the  only  efficient  method,  since  it  alone  prevents  dupli- 
cation and  conflicts  between  the  work  of  various  individuals.  Whether 
this  be  true  or  not,  functionalization  is  readily  apparent  in  most  large 
organizations. 

Process  as  a  basis  of  organization  is  somewhat  more  difficult  to  define. 
Often  it  is  identified  with  a  profession  such  as  engineering,  or  with  a  tech- 
nique such  as  accounting.  Medical  care  wherever  provided — whether 
in  schools,  in  health  centers,  or  in  hospitals— may  be  regarded  as  a  process 
rather  than  as  a  function.  Legal  departments  in  government-— federal,  state, 


142  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

and  local— are  of  a  similar  character,  although  they  are  closely  related  to  the 
function  of  law  enforcement. 

Process  or  profession  is  likely  to  be  found  more  commonly  as  a  basis 
of  staff  organization  than  as  one  of  line  organization.  This  is  a  distinction 
to  which  we  shall  return  later.  It  is  sufficient  here  to  note  that  some  con- 
fusion results  when  we  try  to  define  process  as  a  basis  for  allocating  work. 
It  is  not  always  easy  to  draw  a  line  between  function  and  process.  If  a 
distinction  does  not  readily  appear,  it  may  be  just  as  well  to  consider  the 
two  as  one. 

Clientele  is  much  more  easily  identified  as  a  way  of  dividing  up  work. 
The  Office  of  Indian  Affairs  in  the  Department  of  the  Interior  is  a  good 
example.  This  office  must  provide  education,  welfare,  and  other  services 
for  a  particular  group — the  American  Indian.  The  Department  of  Labor 
also  is  supposed  to  recognize  a  very  important  clientele,  the  labor  element 
of  our  population  as  contrasted  with  professional  and  managerial  personnel. 
The  Children's  Bureau  is  yet  another  illustration  of  clientele  as  the  basis  of 
establishing  a  particular  organization.  A  hospital  for  the  mentally  ill  looks 
toward  a  particular  clientele,  as  does  a  school  for  the  blind  or  deaf.  The 
Veterans  Administration  is  a  further  example.  Any  analysis  of  administra- 
tive structure  will  quickly  reveal  many  instances  where  clientele  has  been 
the  basis  for  determining  institutional  responsibilities. 

Commodity  differentiations  used  for  organization  are  similar  to  those  of 
clientele.  In  any  procurement  operation  some  breakdown  by  commodity 
may  be  expected.  In  the  War  and  Navy  Departments,  supply  activities  are 
divided  along  commodity  lines,  guns  and  ammunition  being  purchased  and 
stored  separately  from  construction  equipment,  aircraft,  medical  supplies, 
communications  equipment,  and  general  supplies. 

Finally,  the  place  where  a  job  is  done — that  is,  the  area — may  be  a  primary 
basis  for  organizing  activities.  The  geographic  factor  is  very  important  in 
administration;  it  will  be  separately  discussed  in  connection  with  decentrali- 
zation. By  their  very  title,  district  offices  suggest  the  geographic  definition 
of  duties.  The  Division  of  Territories  and  Island  Possessions  in  the  Depart- 
ment of  the  Interior  is  an  establishment  that  deals  with  the  problems  of 
particular  areas.  Within  the  War  Department  structure,  the  military  post 
in  the  field  has  long  been  the  center  for  a  number  of  different  activities,  all 
tied  together  by  the  geographic  fact  of  their  location.  The  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority  is  an  outstanding  example  of  an  organization  established  to 
perform  several  different  functions  in  a  designated  area. 

Choice  of  Basis.  Enough  has  been  said  to  afford  some  general  under- 
standing of  the  different  alternatives  available  for  designing  organization. 
Each  has  its  advantages,  but  each  presents  particular  problems.1  It  is 
i  For  a  good  summary  of  the  advantages  and  disadvantages  of  these  bases  of  organization 
see  Gulick,  Luther,  "The  Theory  of  Organization,"  in  Gulick,  L.  and  Urwick,  L.,  eds.,  Papers 
on  the  Science  of  Administration,  pp.  21-30,  New  York:  Institute  of  Public  Administration, 
1937. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  143 

not  necessary  to  debate  relative  merits  in  order  to  gain  a  fundamental  appre- 
ciation of  organizational  problems.  No  one  has  yet  given  us  conclusive 
evidence  that  would  enable  us  to  say  that  there  is  but  one  best  way  to 
organize  for  action.  There  are— as  we  have  seen— four  different  ways,  and 
one  may  present  compelling  arguments  in  a  given  situation.  The  key  lies 
often  in  the  situation,  or  rather  in  a  thoughtful  appreciation  of  the  total 
line-up  of  relevant  factors. 

It  is  not  always  recognized  that  all  of  these  methods  of  organizing  work 
may  be  employed  in  one  agency,  at  succeeding  levels  in  the  division  of 
work.  One  example  may  be  cited.  Under  the  work  relief  program  of  the 
federal  government  from  1935  to  1942,  the  first  breakdown  below  the  level 
of  the  national  office  was  geographic — by  state  boundary  lines.  Status  as 
an  organizationally  separate  state  was  granted  to  New  York  City.  Within 
this  quasi-state  office  at  one  time  were  four  so-called  operating  divisions: 
Operations,  Women's  and  Professional  Projects,  Employment,  and 
Finance.  Operations  referred  to  construction  projects;  in  essence  this 
entailed  a  process.  Women's  and  Professional  Projects,  on  the  other  hand, 
was  a  division  based  on  clientele,  on  the  type  of  person  employed.  Employ- 
ment involved  the  function  of  determining  who  was  eligible  for  work  and 
assigning  those  eligible  to  various  projects.  Finally,  Finance  was  largely  the 
internal  job  of  keeping  project  accounts  and  preparing  payrolls  for  the 
workers.  This  too  could  be  called  a  process,  or,  if  we  choose,  a  function. 
Thus  a  whole  criss-cross  of  organizational  patterns  was  to  be  found  in  this 
one  agency. 

Nor  is  such  a  situation  unique.  Indeed,  we  may  expect  to  find  it  in 
any  large-scale  enterprise.  A  combination  of  organizational  patterns  does 
not  in  itself  suggest  an  undesirable  or  inefficient  structure.  It  may  rightfully 
demand  careful  scrutiny  with  a  view  to  simplification.  However,  we  can- 
not automatically  say  that  an  organization  which  employs  more  than  one 
basis  for  its  division  of  duties  is  a  faulty  organization.  Our  analysis  must 
be  more  penetrating  and  conclusive  than  that. 

Dynamics  and  Rigidities.  As  the  United  States  expanded  from  east  to 
west,  and  as  its  population  increased  sevenfold  in  one  hundred  years,  the 
work  of  its  administrative  agencies  likewise  expanded.  The  changing  na- 
ture of  governmental  activities — particularly  in  depression  and  in  war — 
brought  about  a  further  increase  in  administrative  work.  Some  work  begun 
many  years  ago  has  become  less  important,  if  not  completely  obsolete.  Both 
aspects  of  the  development  entail  alterations  in  organizational  structure 
to  meet  new  conditions.  Shifts  in  emphasis  usually  mean  shifts  in 
organization. 

Yet  there  are  certain  important  elements  of  rigidity  in  administrative 
structure  that  should  never  be  overlooked.  The  history  of  attempts  at  gen- 
eral administrative  reorganization  of  the  federal  government  from  1909  to 
date  reveals  this  fact  only  too  clearly.  Many  agencies  have  cultivated  very 


144  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

close  relations  with  particular  interest  groups.  These  groups  in  turn  have 
opposed  any  move  which  could  be  interpreted  as  tending  to  diminish  the 
importance  of  their  favored  agency— or  impairing  their  own  influence  upon 
its  policy.  Interagency  jealousies  also  played  their  part  in  preventing 
organizational  change.  For  example,  the  rivalry  and  even  hostility  between 
the  National  Park  Service  and  the  United  States  Forest  Service  were 
notorious  in  Washington  ever  since  the  Ballinger-Pinchot  controversy 
of  1909.  This  feud  may  have  been  one  of  the  obstructions  in  the  path  of 
reorganization  proposals  in  1923  and  in  1937,  because  forestry  enthusiasts 
feared  that  the  Forest  Service  might  be  transferred  to  the  Department  of 
the  Interior  and  merged  with  the  Park  Service. 

Moreover,  few  administrators  face  the  problem,  or  the  opportunity,  of 
organizing  their  agency  from  scratch.  Only  when  a  new  agency  is  set  up 
to  undertake  a  new  job  does  the  head  and  his  assistants  have  to  decide  what 
factors  shall  govern  the  division  of  labor.  Most  administrators  inherit  an 
agency,  complete  with  its  existing  structure,  history,  and  traditions. 
Organizational  change  then  becomes  difficult  to  achieve.  Frequently  it  may 
take  a  long  time  and  a  gradual  program  in  order  to  realize  the  desired 
organizational  pattern.  It  makes  little  difference  that  the  nature  of  an 
agency's  work  may  have  greatly  changed  over  a  period  of  years.  Corre- 
sponding alterations  in  structure  which  emphasize  the  new  jobs  and 
consolidate  the  less  important  ones  are  not  easy  of  accomplishment. 

Political  Factors  in  Organization.  The  relative  immobility  of  many  so- 
called  old-line  agencies  is  one  reason  why  chief  executives  often  prefer  the 
creation  of  new  agencies  to  carry  out  new  tasks  rather  than  to  entrust  the 
additional  programs  to  an  existing  agency  with  its  settled  way  of  thinking, 
its  already  solidified  clientele,  and  its  fixed  organizational  traditions.  Rea- 
sons of  general  administrative  logic  may  suggest  that  related  duties  should 
be  assigned  to  an  agency  possessing  some  "know-how."  Reasons  of  high 
policy  may  dictate  the  exact  reverse.  There  is,  in  fact,  no  purely  adminis- 
trative or  organizational  answer  to  this  situation. 

Unfortunately,  organizational  theory  does  not  ordinarily  recognize  the 
personality  factor.  In  reality,  this  is  apt  to  be  an  important  if  not  a  con- 
trolling consideration  in  determining  the  organizational  structure  of  any 
agency.  The  desire  or  need  to  accommodate  a  certain  individual  may  lead 
to  modification  in  structure  simply  for  the  benefit  of  that  individual,  or 
because  consideration  accorded  him  may  secure  more  important  advantages, 
It  has  happened,  for  instance,  that  the  entire  field  organization  of  a  great 
agency  was  adjusted  to  one  top  man  who  insisted  that  he  could  "work"  only 
in  a  direct  command  relationship  to  field  installations.  Many  a  reorganiza- 
tion has  been  wrecked  on  the  reef  of  personality.  The  student  in  the  class- 
room or  the  writer  on  organization  may  pretend  that  personality  factors  are 
unimportant;  the  administrator,  in  determining  organizational  structure, 
may  ignore  them  only  at  his  own  peril. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  145 

We  may  hear  someone  say,  upon  looking  at  an  organization  chart,  "It 
may  work;  it  all  depends  upon  the  individuals  who  are  assigned  to  run  it." 
In  the  present  state  of  our  knowledge  about  public  administration,  it  is 
probably  as  sound  to  pick  key  individuals  and  build  the  organization 
around  them  as  it  is  to  establish  the  administrative  structure  and  then  seek 
the  individuals  to  fill  the  key  posts.  Of  course,  the  first  alternative  would 
not  commend  itself  when  there  is  likelihood  of  continued  turnover  in  the 
key  positions. 

To  repeat,  there  are  at  least  four  different  ways  to  divide  up  any  major 
job,  and  all  four  may  be  used  at  various  levels  in  the  same  agency.  No  one 
way  is  necessarily  the  best.  It  is  vital,  however,  that  the  organizational 
pattern  be  clearly  explained  to  all  who  are  expected  to  help  make  it  work. 
The  personnel  must  understand  how  the  job  is  divided  and  how  the  parts 
fit  together.  Without  this,  no  structure  can  accomplish  its  purpose 
successfully. 

2,  LINE  AND  STAFF 

In  1927,  William  F.  Willoughby  of  the  Institute  for  Government  Re- 
search pointed  out  a  "fundamental  distinction"  between  the  functional  and 
the  institutional  activities  of  governmental  services.2  Functional  activities, 
he  said,  are  those  an  agency  is  expected  to  perform — in  other  words,  the 
objectives  of  the  agency.  Institutional  activities  are  the  work  that  must  be 
done  in  order  to  keep  the  agency  in  operation. 

This  distinction  is  similar  to  another  one  often  made  by  writers  on 
organization;  it  is  the  distinction  between  line  and  staff.  Both  words  have 
a  military  origin,  although  they  are  now  employed  generally  in  civilian 
as  well  as  military  administration. 

v  Meaning  of  Line.  The  word  "line"  is  fairly  simple  to  define.  It  refers 
to  what  in  military  practice  is  termed  the  "chain  of  command."  Line  means 
,the  subordinate  division  of  operating  responsibility.  Thus,  in  the  federal 
government,  we  say  that  the  line  runs  from  the  President  to  department 
heads  to  bureau  chiefs,  and  so  on  downward.  Or  when  the  Federal  Security 
Agency  was  set  up,  the  line  included  the  administrator  of  the  agency,  the 
Social  Security  Board  as  a  directing  unit,  its  executive  director,  the  chiefs 
of  the  Bureaus  of  Old-Age  and  Survivors  Insurance,  Employment  Security, 
and  Public  Assistance,  and  their  operating  subordinates.  Or  in  a  tactical 
military  organization,  the  line  is  made  up  of  the  army  commander,  corps 
commander,  division  commander,  regimental  commander,  battalion  com- 
mander, company  commander,  and  platoon  leader. 

Concepts  about  the  bases  of  organization  would  be  more  clearly  under- 
stood if  it  were  emphasized  that  they  concern  the  division  of  duties  in 
the  line.  Operating  responsibilities  may  be  arranged  functionally  or  by 
purpose,  by  process  or  profession,  by  clientele  or  commodity,  or  geographi- 

2  Willoughby,  W.  F.,  Principles  of  Public  Administration,  p.  105,  Washington:  Brookings 
Institution.  1927. 


146  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

cally.  The  line  is  simply  the  array  of  the  various  succeeding  specializations 
necessary  in  accomplishing  the  task  an  agency  exists  to  perform,  v/ 

Meaning  of  Staff.  Staff,  on  the  other  hand,  is  a  more  complicated  con- 
ception. Many  different  definitions  have  been  attempted.8  The  customary 
starting  point  is  to  say  that  the  staff  is  merely  an  extension  of  the  personality 
of  the  administrator.  The  job  of  management — that  is,  of  the  administrator 
—has  been  set  forth  in  the  specially  contrived  word  POSDCORB.4  These 
are  the  initial  letters  for  planning,  organizing,  staffing,  directing,  coordinat- 
ing, reporting,  and  budgeting.  Here,  it  is  said,  are  the  essentials  with  which 
the  administrator  must  work.  The  units  which  are  set  up  to  assist  him  in 
that  work  are  staff  agencies.  J 

It  is  customary  in  all  writing  about  staff  to  point  out  that  the  operator 
at  or  near  the  base  of  the  organizational  pyramid  needs  no  or  little  staff 
assistance.  The  foreman  is  his  own  staff.  The  superintendent  of  a  depart- 
ment in  a  plant  may  have  only  an  assistant  or  two.  The  plant  manager, 
on  the  other  hand,  may  have  a  number  of  persons  organized  in  various 
units  to  help  him.  Those  familiar  with  tactical  military  organization  know 
that  as  the  progression  climbs  upward  from  platoon  leader  to  company 
commander,  to  battalion  commander,  to  regimental  commander,  and  to 
division  commander,  the  staff  organization  becomes  larger  and  more  fully 
developed.  Thus  in  all  administration  it  is  apparent  that  the  greater  the 
organization  and  the  more  jobs  it  has  to  do,  the  more  staff  assistance  the 
administrator  must  have. 

Since  staffagencies^exist  to  help  the  administrator,  it  is  frequently 
said  that  they  perform  their  work  inrhiniame  dlrtyancT  have  no  command 
authority  of  their  own.  All  power  to  issue  orders  rests  with  the  admin- 
istrator. The  staff  simply  prepares  matters  for  his  action;  it  does  not  issue 
commands  of  its  own.  This  is  supposed  to  be  basic.  It  is  also  pointed  out 
that  the  staff  does  not  operate;  it  only  plaAs,  advises,  suggests,  and  assists. 
Execution  is  left  to  others;  that  is,  the  line.  -J 

These  qualifications  of  staff  have  their  importance,  but  they  are  unduly 
simplified  as  just  stated.  Staff  activity  is  not  so  easy  to  define  or  to  limit. 
Staff  agencies  or  units  often  do  issue  orders  which  the  administrator  never 
sees,  even  though  they  will  reflect  his  interests.  Sometimes  relations  between 
staff  units  at  various  levels  of  the  organizational  hierarchy  are  very  close, 
and  it  would  be  presumptuous  to  say  that  the  higher  units  in  actuality  are 
not  "operating."  Sometimes  the  mass  of  recurrent  work  done  by  staff  units 
is  hard  to  differentiate  from  "operations."  ^ 

Moreover,  there  are  at  least  three  different  types  of  staff  work.  Perhaps 
we  ought  to  say  that  there  are  four,  and  call  planning  a  separate  category  of 
staff  activity.  When  there  is  a  central  planning  agency  in  which  is  concen- 

*  Sec  Urwick,  Lyndall,  "Organization  as  a  Technical  Problem,"  in  Gulick  and  Urwick, 
of.  cit.  in  note  1,  p.  49  ff. 

4  See  Gulick,  ibid.,  p.  12  ff. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  147 

trated  most  of  the  long-range  and  short-range  preparation  for  action,  then 
we  may  rightly  refer  to  planning  as  a  major — and  separate — staff  activity. 
The  previous  discussion  of  planning  has  emphasized  the  crucial  importance 
of  this  phase  of  administration.  Accordingly,  planning  should  be  under* 
stood  as  one  part  of  the  staff  job. 

Staff  Activities  Inherent  in  Administration.  Apart  from  centralized 
planning,  there  remain  three  other  kinds  of  work  which  often  are  called 
staff.  Clear  distinction  between  them  will  prevent  much  confusion.  One 
kind  is  inherent  in  all  administration.  The  most  outstanding  examples  are 
budgeting  and  personnel  activities.  Every  manager  in  public  and  private 
enterprise  usually  must  prepare  in  some  form  an  estimate  of  the  financial 
cost  of  his  work.  This  becomes  a  highly  specialized  job  at  the  higher  levels 
of  administration.  So  also  with  personnel  management.  No  work  can  be 
done  without  the  people  to  perform  it.  Finding,  obtaining,  placing,  and 
keeping  the  people  needed  on  a  job  is  a  continuing  concern.  No  staff  work 
is  more  perennially  a  problem  for  the  administrator  than  budgeting  and 
personnel.  This  work  weaves  back  and  forth  through  all  administration, 
at  almost  any  level. 

Other  activities  may  be  placed  in  the  same  category.  Public  reporting 
and  public  relations  surely  belong  here,  but  they  are  less  well  recognized 
as  such  and  much  less  formalized  in  procedure  than  budgeting  and  per- 
sonnel. Nonetheless,  external  relations  with  the  public  are  implicit  in  much, 
perhaps  all  administration.  Sometimes  the  top  administrator  handles  this 
business  directly,  while  his  subordinates  play  only  supporting  roles. 

Central  Service  Activities.  Another  type  of  staff  work  is  a  central  service 
job  for  the  benefit  of  all  parts  of  an  organization,  or  those  carried  on  in  the 
same  vicinity.  Thus  there  may  be  a  central  reproducing  plant  for  photostat- 
ing or  otherwise  duplicating  materials.  There  may  be  a  central  garage 
or  warehouse.  There  may  be  centralized  procurement  of  the  supplies 
needed  in  running  the  agency,  such  as  desks,  paper,  and  typewriters.  There 
may  be  mail  and  messenger  services  to  provide.  These  are  the  so-called 
institutional  activities  of  an  administrative  agency  in  the  proper  sense.  The 
degree  to  which  such  work  should  be  centralized  is  an  important  question 
of  management  which  we  need  not  debate  here.  The  point  is  that  exten- 
sive services  are  involved  in  running  an  organization;  they  may  be  central- 
ized in  order  to  make  the  fullest  possible  use  of  specialized  facilities  and 
personnel.  When  such  services  are  centralized  and  performed  under  the 
supervision  of  the  top  administrator,  the  combined  unit  is  often  called  a 
staff  facility.  It  is  sometimes  also  described  as  an  "auxiliary"  establishment. 

Functional  and  Operating  Staff.  Finally,  there  are  staff  units  created 
to  guide  or  coordinate  activities  performed  by  operating  units.  This  work 
depends  entirely  upon  the  tasks  of  an  administrative  agency  and  its  primary 
basis  of  organization.  Thus,  in  the  Washington  office  of  the  Forest  Service 
we  encounter  divisions  of  timber  management,  range  management,  wild 


148  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

life  management,  and  fire  control.5  The  divisional  designations  refer  to 
functional  specialties  in  the  Forest  Service  whose  operating  responsibility 
is  organized  geographically.  Similar  staff  units  are  not  likely  to  be  found 
in  many  other  agencies.  In  the  Work  Projects  Administration,  however, 
which  was  also  organized  geographically,  there  were  functional  specialists 
for  educational  projects,  engineering  projects,  recreational  projects,  and  other 
types  of  activity.  In  the  Army  Service  Forces  of  the  War  Department, 
where  procurement  operations  were  divided  basically  by  commodities,  func- 
tional specialists  dealt  with  purchasing  policies,  expediting  of  production 
and  storage. 

Such  supervisory  or  coordinating  staff  activities  in  an  agency  are  deter- 
mined by  the  common  threads  which  run  through  the  operating  units  and 
by  the  decision  to  recognize  some  of  these  threads  for  uniform  management. 
In  the  main,  the  specialists  in  particular  elements  of  administration  are 
likely  to  be  the  staff  personnel  with  vital  coordinating  work  to  be  done  in 
major  operating  fields.  They  are  concerned  with  the  substantive  work  to 
be  accomplished,  and  hence  have  assignments  that  vary  with  the  agency. 
They  are  nonetheless  staff,  even  when  called  the  "functional"  or  "operat- 
ing" staff  in  order  to  differentiate  them  from  those  who  perform  central 
services  or  budget  and  personnel  work. 

One  other  point  needs  to  be  made  about  staff  activities.  Some  agencies 
permit  cleavage  or  hostility  to  develop  between  staff  and  operating  units.  It 
must  always  be  remembered  that  subordinate  managers  who  direct  the 
work  are  also  advisers  to  the  administrator.  The  latter  does  not  look  to 
his  staff  alone  for  counsel;  he  should  and  does  look  also  to  his  subordinate 
managers  or  operators,  since  they  too  are  expected  to  see  the  work  not 
merely  in  its  component  parts  but  as  a  whole.  Staff  specialists  and  operators 
both  make  up  an  organization.  They  must  work  together.6 

3.  THE  QUEST  OF  ORGANIZATIONAL  UNITY 

Hierarchy  and  Span  of  Control.   Sometimes  administrative  structure  is 
|  described  as  pyramidal.  This  is  merely  another  way  of  expressing  the  con- 
.ception  of  hierarchy.   As  already  indicated,  organization  begins  with  some 
broad  purpose  to  be  accomplished,  and  proceeds  by  dividing  the  job  into 
^various  component  parts.  As  each  new  subdivision  is  created,  the  number 
of  parts  multiplies.  From  one  person  at  the  top,  the  organizational  struc- 
ture breaks  down  into  various  superintendents,  then  to  foremen  or  super- 
visors, and  finally  to  workers—the  base  of  the  triangle.  This  has  been  called 
the  "scalar"  process  or  principle  in  organization. 

5  Sec  Loveridge,  Earl  W.  and  Keplinger,  Peter,  "Washington-Field  Relationships  in  the 
Forest  Service,"  in  Washington-Field  Relationships  in  the  Federal  Service,  p.  23  ff.,  Washington: 
Graduate  School  of  the  United  States  Depirtment  of  Agriculture,  1942. 

*  Staff  officers  need  a  clear  understanding,  of  the  personal  and  psychological  demands 
inherent  in  their  role.  For  an  excellent  statement  of  how  a  staff  officer  should  act,  see  Bellah, 
Lt.  Coi.  James  W.,  "Staff  Officer,"  Infantry  Journal,  1944,  Vol.  55  (No.  2),  p.  43  ff. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  149 

The  Catholic  Church  has  long  afforded  an  excellent  illustration  of 
hierarchy.  At  the  base  of  the  structure  is  the  parish  priest.  Above  the  priest 
is  the  bishop  of  the  diocese;  in  turn  a  number  of  bishops  are  grouped  under 
an  archbishop;  and  finally  over  the  archbishop  is  the  Pope  in  Rome. 
The  triangular  infantry  division  used  as  the  basic  tactical  organization 
by  the  United  States  in  World  War  II  is  another  example  of  hierarchy. 
Four  companies  made  a  battalion,  three  battalions  a  regiment,  and  three 
regiments  a  division. 

Hierarchy  means  the  grouping  of  units  into  a  larger  unit  for  direc- 
tion and  control  of  activities.  It  is  the  method  whereby  the  efforts  of  many 
different  individuals  are  geared  together.  Hierarchy  is  another  indispensable 
feature  of  large-scale  enterprise.  Only  through  hierarchical  relationships 
can  unified  direction  be  achieved  from  one  central  point,  and  broad  purposes 
be  translated  into  action.  This  should  not  suggest,  of  course,  that  hierarchy 
may  be  relied  upon  as  a  substitute  for  cooperation. 

The  importance  of  hierarchy  is  underlined  by  another  organizational 
concept — span  of  control.  Any  one  individual  can  effectively  supervise  only 
a  limited  number  of  persons.  Certain  administrators  and  students  have 
made  this  limitation  specific — no  more  than  seven,  nine,  or  twelve  indi- 
viduals should  report  to  the  same  superior.  Today  it  is  generally  agreed 
that  the  number  of  individuals  a  person  can  direct  depends  upon  several 
factors,  especially  the  routine  nature  of  the  work,  the  place  where  the  job 
is  done,  and  the  energy  of  the  supervisor.  It  is  easier  to  supervise  many 
individuals  when  each  is  doing  the  same  work,  when  that  work  is  of  a 
repetitive  nature,  and  when  it  is  performed  close  together.  A  limited  num- 
ber of  contacts  for  any  one  superior  is  nonetheless  essential  in  order  to 
ensure  adequate  supervision  and  coordinated  action. 

Decentralization.  Closely  allied  to  the  concepts  of  hierarchy  and  span  of 
control  is  the  concept  of  decentralization.  This  is  another  word  with  at 
least  two  administrative  meanings— quite  aside  from  the  political  one  in 
the  sense  of  states'  rights  and  institutions  of  local  self-government.7  In  one 
administrative  sense,  decentralization — as  deconcentration — is  synonymous 
with  delegation  of  authority.  It  refers  to  the  assignment  of  responsibilities 
in  such  a  way  that  substantial  areas  of  discretion  are  entrusted  to  subordi- 
nate officers,  thus  preventing  dangerous  bottlenecks  and  overwork  for  the 
administrator  at  the  apex  of  the  hierarchy.  We  often  speak  of  highly  cen- 


7  The  word  "decentralization"  has  been  used  by  some  to  refer  exclusively  to  the  federal 
system,  whereby  governmental  authority  is  divided  between  national  and  state  executives  and 
legislatures.  The  grant-in-aid  system — described  in  Key,  V.  O.,  The  Administration  of  Federal 
Grants  to  States,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1937,  and  Clark,  Jane  P.,  The  Rist 
of  a  New  Federalism,  New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1938 — is  a  means  of  promoting 
national  programs  through  state  administrative  agencies.  Because  of  the  use  of  the  wore 
"decentralization'*  to  describe  federal -state  relationships,  some  have  suggested  the  word  "decon- 
centration" to  describe  interlevel  or  headquarters -field  relationships  in  a  particular  agency.  Foi 
a  more  detailed  discussion  see  the  symposium  entitled  Washington-Field  Relationships  in  tht 
Federal  Service  cited  in  note  5.  This  matter  is  taken  up  below  in  Ch.  12,  "Field  Organization/ 


150  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

tralized  administration  when  we  really  mean  that  many  actions  require 
prior  approval  from  the  chief  or  one  of  his  assistants.  Conversely,  we  may 
think  of  a  highly  decentralized  administration  as  one  that  is  characterized 
by  broad  grants  of  power  to  individual  component  parts  of  the  organiza- 
tion, with  the  retention  of  only  certain  essential  controls  in  the  head  office. 

Decentralization,  however,  has  yet  another  meaning,  perhaps  growing 
out  of  the  one  just  circumscribed.  It  may  refer  to  field  organization,  to  the 
number  of  units  operating  away  from  the  central  office.  The  problems  of 
field  organization  are  discussed  later  in  this  book,  and  it  is  necessary  to 
note  here  only  that  decentralization  has  also  a  geographic  aspect,  involving 
the  type  of  field  structure  and  the  authority  granted  to  field  units.  Much 
emphasis  has  been  given  to  decentralization — as  deconcentration — in  recent 
years,  because  it  has  been  discovered  that  rapid  action  in  any  large  effort 
depends  in  considerable  measure  upon  the  extensive  delegation  of  authority 
to  subordinate  officers  or  field  establishments.  ' 

Unity  of  Command.  Still  another  concept  often  mentioned  in  discus- 
sions of  organization  is  unity  of  command.  This  expression  may  refer  to 
the  desirability  of  having  each  subordinate  in  the  chain  of  command  report 
to  a  single  individual.  Or  it  may  refer  to  an  arrangement  whereby  all  ad- 
ministrative authority  flows  from  one  responsible  head,  be  he  President  of 
the  United  States,  governor  of  a  state,  or  president  of  a  great  corporation. 
And  finally,  the  concept  may  refer  to  the  question  of  the  relative  mer- 
its of  a  single-headed  agency  as  compared  with  those  of  a  board  or 
commission. 

Much  importance  is  usually  placed  upon  the  construction  of  an  adminis- 
trative arrangement  wherein  each  person  has  only  one  superior  to  whom 
he  looks  for  direction.  In  such  a  setup  an  individual  cannot  receive  con- 
flicting instructions,  or  play  one  superior  off  against  another  and  thus 
escape  effective  supervision.  On  the  other  hand,  when  the  subordinate  is 
subject  to  multiple  sources  of  command,  confusion  may  arise  and  respon- 
sibility for  action  may  be  difficult  to  fix.  Administrative  expedience  has 
shown  this  to  be  a  cardinal  factor  in  connection  with  general  efficiency. 
Yet  there  are  practical  conditions  which  on  occasion  may  dictate  the  crea- 
tion or  continuance  of  a  situation  where  one  has  two  superiors.  The  con- 
cept of  unity  of  command  therefore  needs  to  be  reconciled  with  a  recogni- 
tion that  supervision  of  any  activity  may  be  dual — technical  and  also  admin- 
istrative.8 The  two  types  of  supervision  may  be  exercised  by  different 
individuals.  The  one  type  may  be  concerned  with  professional  competence 
in  the  performance  of  a  job,  while  the  other  is  chiefly  interested  in  the  effi- 
cient utilization  of  the  resources— men  and  materials— available  for  the  job. 

Administrative  responsibility  is  of  especial  concern  in  a  democracy.  Our 
great  governmental  machinery  must  be  kept  responsive  to  changes  in  politi- 

8  Sec  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  Millett,  John  D.  and  Ogdcn,  G.,  The  Administration  of 
Federal  Wor\  Relief,  ch.  11,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1941. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  151 

cal  opinion.  When  party  control  in  the  presidency  changes,  for  example, 
we  expect  the  new  incumbent  to  be  able  to  make  his  policies  effective 
throughout  the  administrative  agencies  of  government.  Yet  an  unequivocal 
adoption  of  this  policy  has  never  occurred  either  in  our  national  government 
or  in  most  of  our  states  and  cities.  Instead,  we  have  used  in  many  instances 
a  different  kind  of  arrangement,  which  has  led  to  another  concept — that  of 
administrative  autonomy. 

Our  great  regulatory  commissions,  exercising  so-called  quasi-legislative 
and  quasi-judicial  authority,  are  often  referred  to  as  independent  agencies. 
Their  peculiar  status  is  embodied  in  the  law,  and  the  Supreme  Court  has 
held  that  a  member  of  such  a  commission  may  not  be  removed  at  will  by 
the  President.9  Government  corporations  have  also  been  viewed  as  inde- 
pendent, particularly  when  they  were  free  to  handle  their  funds  under  their 
own  procedure  and  to  appoint  personnel  regardless  of  civil  service  provisions. 
There  is  no  "unity  of  command"  over  these  agencies.  Responsible  direction 
is  confused,  to  say  the  least. 

The  practice  of  creating  boards  and  commissions  to  exercise  administra- 
tive authority  is  fairly  extensive  throughout  federal,  state,  and  local  govern- 
ment. Many  students  will  readily  accept  the  famous  dictum  that  boards 
are  "long,  narrow,  and  wooden."  There  is  undoubtedly  a  place  for  boards 
in  administration,  as  deliberative  or  consultative  devices.  However,  it  is 
quite  widely  recognized  now  that  any  activity  requiring  positive  action  and 
leadership  can  best  be  directed  by  a  single  individual.  Boards  violate  the 
concept  of  "unity  of  command."  They  make  rapid  action  difficult.  We  may 
admit  that  unity  of  command  is  an  organizational  objective,  but  it  can 
scarcely  be  called  an  adequate  description  of  actual  administrative  practice 
in  our  government  today.10 

9  Humphrey's  Executor  v.  United  States,  295  U.  S.  602  (1935). 

10  On  the  whole  problem  of  the  organizational  position  of  the  regulatory  commissions, 
see  Cushman,  Robert  E.,  The  Independent  Regulatory  Commissions,  esp.  chs.  10-13,  New  York: 
Oxford  University  Press,  1941.   For  a  study  of  state  regulatory  agencies,  see  Fcsler,  James  W., 
The  Independence  of  State  Regulatory  Agencies,  Chicago:   Public  Administration  Service,  1942, 
For  fuller  discussion,  see  below  Ch.  10,  "Independent  Regulatory  Establishments." 

There  is  extensive  writing  on  the  subject  of  government  corporations.  See  particularly, 
Van  Dorn,  Harold  A.,  Government-Owned  Corporations,  New  York:  Knopf,  1926;  Dimock, 
Marshall  E.,  Government-Owned  Enterprises  in  the  Panama  Canal  Zone,  Chicago:  University 
of  Chicago  Press,  1934,  and  Developing  America's  Waterways,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago 
Press,  1935;  Emmerich,  Herbert,  "Government  Corporations  and  Independent  Supervisory 
Agencies,"  in  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special 
Studies,  p.  299  ff.,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937;  Thurston,  John,  Government 
Proprietary  Corporations  in  the  English-Speaking  Countries,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University 
Press,  1937;  McDiarmid,  John,  Government  Corporations  and  Federal  Funds,  Chicago:  Uni- 
versity of  Chicago  Press,  1938;  and  Pritchett,  C.  Herman,  "The  Paradox  of  the  Government 
Corporation,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  381  ff.  For  fuller  discussion, 
see  below  Ch.  11,  "Government  Corporations." 

The  best  statement  on  the  use  and  limitations  of  boards  is  to  be  found  in  a  small 
pamphlet  by  Urwick,  L.,  Committees  in  Organization,  London,  1935  (reprinted  from  the 
British  Management  Review). 


152  WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 

Coordination.  There  are  yet  two  other  terms  frequently  encountered  in 
discussions  of  organization.  These  are  "coordination"  and  "integration." 
Often  they  appear  coupled  together  as  if  complementary.  Actually,  the 
two  words  describe  very  different  structural  arrangements.  Indeed,  coordi- 
nation does  not  refer  to  organization  except  indirectly.  Rather  it  is  a  phase 
of  management,  a  part  of  the  job  of  supervision.  Coordination  is  achieved 
when  harmonious  action  prevails  between  the  operating  parts  of  an  agency. 
The  techniques  of  coordination  run  through  the  whole  range  of  supervisory 
tools:  careful  planning  of  the  job,  clear  definition  of  responsibility,  establish- 
ment of  reporting  obligations,  inspection  of  work,  conferences  of  key  per- 
sonnel, proper  and  convenient  channels  of  communication,  higher  approval 
of  action  proposed  by  subordinates.  And  the  list  could  be  extended. 

Organizationally,  the  first  problem  of  coordination  is  to  ensure  that  there 
are  adequate  staff  facilities  to  help  exercise  the  necessary  authority.  Coordi- 
nation must  be  achieved  by  providing  the  administrator  with  competent 
assistance.  Wherever  there  are  important  subjects  of  common  interest  to 
different  operating  agencies  or  units;  wherever  their  fields  of  activities  tend 
to  duplicate  or  overlap;  wherever  it  is  necessary  to  have  common  problems 
of  operating  units  handled  on  a  common  basis — in  all  such  situations  a 
coordinating  staff  is  needed. 

On  the  other  hand,  staff  coordination  may  develop  difficulties.  Staff 
works  in  the  name  of  the  administrator,  but  the  operating  official  may  still 
go  to  the  boss  and  protest  what  may  look  to  him  like  direct  staff  instruc- 
tions. A  large  organization  may  have  many  staff  facilities,  thus  increasing 
the  number  of  subordinates  reporting  to  the  administrator.  As  operating 
agencies  multiply  and  perform  increased  work,  there  is  often  a  tendency 
to  enlarge  the  staff  of  the  administrator  at  the  same  time.  The  result  may 
be  confusion  arising  from  a  desire  by  the  staff  to  assume  more  and  more 
operating  authority;  another  result  may  be  congestion  or  overcrowding 
at  the  top. 

Integration.  Integration  offers  a  possible  solution  for  situations  like 
these.  Integration  means  the  combination  of  operating  units  under  an  addi- 
tional administrative  official  interposed  between  them  and  the  top  adminis- 
trator. The  interposed  individual  is  not  a  staff  officer  but  a  line  adminis- 
trator. He  commands  the  group  of  combined  units,  and  thereby  reduces  the 
number  of  operating  officials  reporting  to  the  top  man. 

An  example  of  coordination  proceeding  toward  integration  is  afforded 
by  housing  experience  during  World  War  II.  Prior  to  the  war,  there  were 
a  Federal  Housing  Administration  and  a  Federal  Home  Loan  Bank  Board 
in  the  Federal  Loan  Agency,  and  a  United  States  Housing  Authority  in  the 
Federal  Works  Agency.  The  need  for  handling  the  urban  housing  problem 
on  a  uniform  basis  during  the  defense  period  led  the  President  to  create, 
by  Executive  Order  No.  8632  of  January  11,  1941,  a  Division  of  Defense 
Housing  Coordination  in  the  Office  for  Emergency  Management,  part  of 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  153 

his  Executive  Office.  This  was  a  move  in  the  direction  of  coordinating 
housing  programs  by  setting  up  a  staff  officer  in  the  housing  field,  with  the 
President  as  the  direct  head  over  the  Federal  Loan  Agency  and  the 
Federal  Works  Agency.  When,  for  various  reasons,  this  effort  did  not 
succeed,  the  President,  by  Executive  Order  No.  9070  of  February  24,  1942, 
established  under  his  war  powers  the  National  Housing  Agency.  Into 
the  new  agency  went  as  its  three  component  parts  a  Federal  Public  Hous- 
ing Authority  (formerly  the  USHA),  the  Federal  Housing  Administration, 
and  the  Federal  Home  Loan  Bank  Board.  The  President  now  had  one 
man  to  look  to  in  the  housing  field — the  administrator  of  the  National 
Housing  Agency.  Previously  he  had  had  to  deal  with  three — his  staff 
officer  on  housing  and  the  heads  of  the  Federal  Works  and  Loan  Agencies.11 
Coordination  can  be  achieved  through  staff  planning  and  supervision. 
Integration  is  the  means  for  reducing  the  structural  diversity  of  too  elabo- 
rate an  organization,  or  for  lightening  the  burden  on  a  central  staff.  In 
effect,  integration  introduces  a  new  level  in  the  organizational  hierarchy — 
a  new  level  of  coordinating  authority.  The  added  line  administrator  will  be 
able  directly  to  iron  out  difficulties  between  subordinate  units.  Fewer  issues 
will  then  require  coordination  at  the  next  higher  level.  Integration  is  the 
organizational  device  which  will  cut  down  a  top  administrator's  load.  Co- 
ordination simply  sees  to  it  that  he  performs  his  role  and  carries  his  load. 

4.   GUIDING  RULES  OF  ORGANIZATIONAL  DESIGN 

"Need  for  Standards  of  Organization.  There  have  been  attempts  from 
time  to  time  to  formulate  guides  or  standards  of  organization.  While  our  dis- 
cussion has  briefly  outlined  the  major  problems  in  organization,  it  has  pro- 
vided no  answers  for  those  with  organizing  responsibility.  The  need  for 
some  positive  guidance  to  administrators  in  fixing  organizational  structure 
has  often  been  felt.  This  in  turn  has  led  various  students  to  set  up  standards 
of  what  is  assumed  to  be  good  organization. 


11  There  is  a  great  deal  of  literature  about  general  problems  of  organization.  The  follow- 
ing are  listed  as  a  few  of  the  major  contributions  to  the  subject:  Gulick  and  Urwick,  op.  cit. 
in  note  1;  Gaus,  John  M.  and  Others,  The  Frontiers  of  Public  Administration,  Chicago:  Uni- 
versity of  Chicago  Press,  1936;  Willoughby,  op.  cit.  in  note  2;  Snrth,  Edgar  W.,  "Relation 
of  Organization  to  Management,"  in  the  symposium  entitled  Administrative  Management, 
p.  53  ff.,  Washington:  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  Graduate  School,  1938;  and 
Senate  Select  Committee  to  Investigate  the  Executive  Agencies  of  the  Government,  Preliminary 
Report,  75th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1937.  Cf.  also  Hopf,  Harry  A.,  "Administrative 
Coordination,"  in  Morstcin  Marx,  Fritz,  cd.,  Public  Management  in  the  N'tv  Democracy, 
p.  83  ff.,  New  York:  Harper,  1940;  Urwick,  L.,  The  Elements  of  Administration,  New  York: 
Harper,  1943;  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  The  Executive  in  Action,  New  York:  Harper,  1945;  and 
Hopf,  Harry  A.,  "Soundings  in  the  Literature  of  Management,"  Advanced  Management,  1945, 
Vol.  10,  p.  93  ff. 

Among  the  many  books  about  organization  of  private  enterprise,  see  Mooney,  James  D. 
and  Reiley,  Alan  C.,  The  Principles  of  Organization,  New  York:  Harper,  1939,  and  Holden, 
Paul  E.,  Fish,  Lounsbury  S.  and  Smith,  Hubert  L.,  Top  Management  Organization  and  Con- 
trol, Stanford:  Stanford  University  Press,  1941. 


154 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 


Necessarily  these  standards  have  been  general  in  terms;  they  have  sug- 
gested pitfalls  to  avoid  as  much  as  positive  action  to  take.  Three  of  these 
efforts  at  stating  enduring  guideposts  of  organization  are  summarized  in 
comparative  tabular  form  below.  The  selection  may  be  regarded  as  repre- 
sentative of  all  efforts  to  formulate  organizational  standards. 


ENSURING  SOUND  ORGANIZATION 


1.  Definite  and  clean-cut 
responsibilities  should 
be  assigned  to  each 
executive. 


2.  Responsibility     should 
always  be  coupled  with 
corresponding    author- 
ity. 

3.  No  change  should  be 
made  in  the  scope  or 
responsibilities     of     a 
position      without      a 
definite  understanding 
to  that  effect  on   the 
part  of  all  concerned. 


4.  No  executive  or  em- 
ployee, occupying  a 
single  position  in  the 
organization,  should 
be  subject  to  definite 
orders  from  more  than 
one  source. 


5. ,  Orders  should  never 
be  given  to  subordi- 
nates over  the  head  of 
a  responsible  executive. 
Rather  than  do  this 
the  officer  in  question 
should  be  supplanted. 


II** 

1.  Definite  responsibil- 
ity   and    authority 
should     be     estab- 
lished for  all  posi- 
tions. 

(a)  Authority  must  be 
commensurate  with 
responsibility. 

2.  Organization  of  the 
department    should 
be   clearly   defined. 
.  .  .  Organization  is 
an     ever  -  changing 
vehicle  of  manage- 
ment     and      thus 
must     be     molded 
through  the  use  of 
executive  orders, 
bulletins,    office 
memoranda,  and 
.  .  .  frequent  staff 
and  individual  con- 
ferences. 

3.  The    leadership    of 
the  department  as  a 
whole  and  of  each 
of  its  line  subdivi- 
sions should  be  sin- 
gle and  direct. 


Ill*** 

1.  Definite  and  clean- 
cut     responsibilities 
should  be  assigned 
to    each    employee, 
particularly  the  key 
employees. 

2.  Responsibility  must 
be  accompanied  by 
reasonably  complete 
authority. 


3.  No  employee,  oc- 
cupying a  single 
position  in  an  or- 
ganization, should 
be  subject  to  defi- 
nite orders  from 
more  than  one  per- 
son. 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 


155 


ENSURING  SOUND  ORGANIZATION — Continued 

II**  III*** 


6.  Criticisms  of  subordi- 
nates should,  whenever 
possible,  be  made  pri- 
vately, and  in  no  case 
should    a    subordinate 
be    criticized    in    the 
presence  of  executives 
or  employees  of  equal 
or  lower  rank. 

7.  No  dispute  or  differ- 
ence   between    execu- 
tives or  employees  as 
to  authority  or  respon- 
sibilities     should      be 
considered    too   trivial 
for  prompt  and  careful 
adjudication. 

8.  Promotions,    wage 
changes,   and   discipli- 
nary action  should  al- 
ways be  approved  by 
the  executive  immedi- 
ately   superior    to   the 
one    directly   responsi- 
ble. 

9.  No   executive   or  em- 
ployee should  ever  be 
required,  or  expected', 
to  be  at  the  same  time 
an    assistant    to,    and 
critic  of,  another. 

10.  Any  executive  whose 
work  is  subject  to  reg- 
ular inspection  should', 
whenever  practicable, 
be  given  the  assistance 
and  facilities  necessary 
to  enable  him  to  main- 
tain an  independent 
check  of  the  quality  of 
his  work. 


4.  The  director  of  the 
department    and 
each  division  chief 
should    be    assisted 
in  their  administra- 
tive   responsibilities 
by  the  management 
and    staff   activities 
under  their  author- 
ity. 

5.  No  administrator  of 
a  department  or  di- 
vision should  have 
reporting    to    him 
more  persons  than 
he   can   adequately 
supervise. 


5. 


Wherever  possible, 
an  independent 
check  of  an  em- 
ployee's  work 
should  be  made 
and  the  results  of 
the  check  should  be 
made  available  to 
the  employee  in  as 
helpful  a  manner 
as  possible. 
Not  more  than 
three  to  six  em- 
ployees who  are 
charged  with  im- 
portant and  varied 
responsibilities 
should  be  subject 
to  the  direct  orders 
of  the  same  man. 


156 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION 
ENSURING  SOUND  ORGANIZATION — Continued 


I*  II**  III*** 

6.  Veto  power  must 
be  given  only  to 
persons  who  are 
charged  with  re- 
sponsibility for  the 
results  of  their 
vetoes. 

6.  The  main  subdivi- 
sions of  the  depart- 
ment    should     be 
based      upon      an 
analysis  of  the  ac- 
tivities  carried    on, 
with    all    activities 
which  are  alike  in 
scope  or  technique, 
or  which  require  a 
similar  type  of  su- 
pervision,   grouped 
together. 

7.  Positions  should  be 
determined    insofar 
as  possible  irrespec- 
tive of  individuals, 
on  the  basis  of  the 
various    classes    of 
work    to    be    per- 
formed. 

8.  Coordination  of  the 
work  and  personnel 
of  the  several  ma- 
jor divisions  of  the 
department    should 
be  the  primary  con- 
cern of  the  depart- 
ment director. 

*"Tcn  Commandments  of  Good  Organization,"  prepared  by  the  American  Management 
Association  and  quoted  in  Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  p.  80,  note  1. 

**From  Stone,  Donald  C.,  The  Management  of  Municipal  Public  Worths,  pp.  7-8,  Chicago: 
Public  Administration  Service,  1939  (by  permission  of  the  publisher). 

***  Principles  developed  by  the  Surplus  Marketing  Administration  and  reported  by 
Allsetter,  W.  R.,  in  Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  p.  80  ff.  (by  permission 
of  the  editor). 

Summary.  Our  working  concepts  of  organization  are  founded  on  gen- 
eral observations  which  have  crystallized  from  experience.  Four  primary 
bases  are  in  common  use  for  dividing  up  operating  responsibilities.  It  is  of 
practical  value  to  recognize  the  differences  between  line  and  staff,  between 


WORKING  CONCEPTS  OF  ORGANIZATION  157 

the  operating  work  which  accomplishes  the  end-purpose  of  administrative 
effort  and  the  work  that  is  done  to  keep  the  organization  fit  for  effective 
action.  The  operating  job  is  broken  down  into  various  levels  of  supervision. 
This  is  the  foundation  of  hierarchy.  Ideally,  we  want  a  single  line  of  author- 
ity throughout  the  hierarchy;  that  is,  we  want  unity  of  command.  How- 
ever, the  concept  of  unity  of  command  must  allow  for  a  distinction  between 
technical  supervision  and  administrative  supervision  since  the  one  is  con- 
cerned with  specialized  professional  work  and  the  other  with  general 
efficiency  and  performance.  Coordination  is  necessary  among  operating 
units,  but  when  the  coordinating  burden  becomes  large,  a  new  level  of 
supervision  may  be  introduced  through  integration. 

Generalizations  about  organization  must  be  modified  because  of  per- 
sonality factors  and  because  of  peculiar  circumstances  of  time  and  place. 
There  are  no  final  answers  to  all  organizational  problems,  even  though  we 
do  have  signposts  for  our  guidance  in  applying  the  working  concepts  of 
organization. 

Management  is  common  to  all  public  enterprise,  whether  the  ultimate 
product  is  flood  control,  military  defense,  or  collection  of  taxes.  That  is 
why  the  general  body  of  public  administration  as  a  field  of  knowledge 
deals  with  common  problems.  These  make  up  the  realm  of  interchangeable 
experience  in  public  administration.  At  the  same  time,  we  should  never 
forget  that  we  are  talking  only  about  ways  and  means,  about  techniques 
and  processes.  It  is  the  administrative  end-product  that  is  of  first  impor- 
tance. Our  deeper  concern  is  with  organizing  to  achieve  that  end-product 
for  the  benefit  of  the  community,  with  the  least  depletion  of  available 
resources. 


CHAPTER 


The  Chief  Executive 

1.  DUAL  FUNCTION:  POLICY  AND  ADMINISTRATION 

Means  and  Ends.CAt  its  highest  reach,  administrative  management  is 
so  closely  intertwined  with  leadership  in  policy  development  that  in  most 
governmental  jurisdictions  and  in  nearly  all  private  organizations  both 
functions  are  intentionally  lodged  in  the  same  top  man.  This  is  the  central 
fact  setting  off  the  position  of  the  chief  executive  from  those  of  all  lesser 
administrative  officers,  whether  they  be  called  executives,  administrators, 
managers,  or  by  some  other  title.  It  is  our  purpose  in  the  present  chapter 
to  describe  and  analyze  this  most  important  of  all  offices  in  public  adminis- 
tration by  focusing  on  five  basic  aspects:  the  duality  of  the  executive's 
functions;  leadership  and  authority;  external  relationships;  the  tools  needed 
for  effective  control;  and  the  arms  of  modern  management. 

The  justification  for  studying  administration  apart  from  other  phases  of 
government  rests,  as  we  saw  earlier,  on  the  possibility  and  the  utility  of 
distinguishing  between  political  ends  and  administrative  means.  Of  course, 
acceptance  of  the  validity  of  this  distinction  in  no  way  denies  the  fact  that 
there  are  higher  and  lower  levels  of  administration  and  of  policy.  Nor  does 
it  place  in  doubt  the  necessity  for  differing  degrees  of  initiative  and  discre- 
tion to  be  exercised  throughout  the  entire  range  of  political  power  and 
administrative  authority. 

Lesser  ends  are  themselves  means  toward  greater  ends,  and  higher 
means  are  intermediate  ends  reached  by  lower  means.  The  need  for  deci- 
sion is  everywhere  the  same,  and,  wherever  a  decision  must  be  made,  there 
in  one  sense  both  a  question  of  policy  and  a  question  of  administration 
have  to  be  decided.  If  for  intellectual  convenience  we  abstract  from  the 
general  context  sometimes  the  one,  sometimes  the  other,  life  remains  none 
the  less  tangled  and  connected.  Yet  schemes  and  symbols  of  analysis  have 
great  value  if  their  limitations  are  borne  in  mind. 

(j[f  the  accent  be  on  policy — that  is,  on  ends — we  may,  for  instance,  observe 
that  even  where  major  policy  decisions  are  made  by  individuals  holding 

158 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  159 

political  responsibility,  minor  policy  decisions  will  still  be  left  to  administra- 
tive officers.  Does  this  mean  that  the  distinction  between  politics  and 
administration  is  faulty?  Not  at  all.  It  merely  recognizes  that  below  the 
plane  of  political  policy-determination  lie  other  planes — planes  of  adminis- 
trative policy—on  which  also  questions  of  alternative  courses  of  action  have 
to  be  decided.  Conversely,  if  the  accent  be  on  means — that  is,  on  alterna- 
tives of  administration— we  should  acknowledge  that  above  the  issues  of 
administrative  machinery  and  procedure  lie  issues  of  political  ways  and 
means.  Administrative  preferences  therefore  may  have  to  yield  to  neces- 
sities of  politics.  <^Political  politics"  and  "administrative  administration" 
give  only  the  broad  outlines  of  the  picture  of  government;  the  full  portrait 
calls  for  the  lights  and  shadings  of  administrative  politics  and  political 
management.) 

In  the  whole  realm  of  government  perhaps  no  one  appreciates  the 
truth — or  the  importance — of  this  proposition  so  much  as  the  chief  execu- 
tive. The  President  of  the  United  States,  the  governors  of  New  York, 
Pennsylvania,  and  California,  and  the  mayors  of  New  York  City,  Chicago, 
Philadelphia,  Detroit,  St.  Louis,  Los  Angeles,  and  Boston,  as  responsible 
heads  of  the  executive  branch  in  our  largest  governmental  jurisdictions,  fur- 
nish outstanding  illustrations  of  the  range  and  complexity  of  the  responsi- 
bilities inherent  in  this  office.  Yet  abilities  of  the  same  kind  if  not  of  the 
same  order  are  needed  at  the  helm  of  every  sizable  administrative  establish- 
ment whatever  the  governmental  level — in  the  governorship  of  each  state, 
in  the  mayoralty  of  every  urban  community,  in  the  top  office  of  scores  of 
thousands  of  other  units  of  local  government,  and  also  in  the  direction  of 
all  large  administrative  departments. 

Separation  of  Political  Leadership  and  Administration.  Before  proceed- 
ing into  an  analysis  of  the  chief  executive  in  his  typical  role,  let  us  examine 
briefly  several  types  of  situations  in  which  the  responsibilities  of  policy  devel- 
opment and  administrative  direction  are  assigned  to  different  officials  rather 
than  concentrated  in  a  single  individual.  Turning  first  to  instances  of  such 
separation  outside  government,  we  may  note  the  common  practice  among 
business  corporations  of  vesting  responsibility  for  corporate  policy  in  a  board 
of  directors  headed  by  a  chairman  and  delegating  corporate  management  to 
a  president  or  general  manager. 

Election  as  chairman  of  the  board  expresses  recognition  of  demonstrated 
initiative  and  intelligence  in  policy  leadership.  Elevation  to  this  position 
signifies  above  everything  else  the  primacy  of  company  policy.  While  the 
president  or  general  manager  may  also  be  a  director,  his  first  duty  is  the 
effective  execution  of  whatever  policies  the  board  may  adopt.  Nor  are  busi- 
ness corporations  the  only  organizations  employing  such  a  division  of  basic 
responsibilities.  The  way  the  presidents  of  many  private  colleges  and  uni- 
versities, and  other  nongovernmental  institutions  and  associations  as  well, 


160  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

stand  inflation,  to  the  chairmen  of  their  boards  of  trustees  or  regents  fol- 
lows the  same  pattern. 

There  are  fewer  clear  examples  of  such  separation  within  govern- 
ment. Perhaps  the  most  striking  illustration  is  furnished  by  municipal 
organization  under  what  ought  to  be  called  for  the  sake  of  completeness  the 
mayor-council-manager  plan.  The  theory  behind  this  soundest  of  all  forms 
of  municipal  government  is  perfectly  plain.  Policy  leadership  is  the  respon- 
sibility of  the  council,  and  particularly  of  its  chairman,  the  mayor — whether 
he  be  chosen  by  the  council  or  elected  by  the  voters.  The  city  manager's  job 
is  confined  to  advising  with  the  mayor  and  council  on  matters  requiring 
their  decision,  and  administering  the  work  program  which  they  adopt. 

Other  examples  may  be  found  in  the  field  of  public  education.  Insofar 
as  underlying  theory  is  concerned — and  the  facts  themselves  are  more  or 
less  in  line  with  it — the  relations  between  local  boards  of  education  and 
their  superintendents  of  schools  are  like  those  prevailing  under  the  council- 
manager  plan.  The  same  applies  to  the  relations  between  state  boards  of 
education  and  the  presidents,  chancellors,  and  provosts  of  state  colleges 
and  universities. 

One  other  situation  remains  to  be  mentioned  in  the  same  context.  In 
the  more  recent  past  not  a  few  governmental  agencies — national,  state,  and 
local — have  found  it  productive  of  good  administration  within  their  own 
organizations  to  distinguish  consciously  between  policy  concerns  and  man- 
agement responsibilities.  Commenting  on  the  general  necessity  for  "a  com- 
mon focus  for  management  facilities  either  in  an  administratively  minded 
department  head  or  in  a  general  administrator  working  in  close  association 
with  the  policy  leadership  of  the  agency,"  Donald  C.  Stone  in  1943  of- 
fered this  brief  summary  of  specific  though  tentative  develoments  in  the 
federal  government:1 

A  few  years  ago  observers  thought  they  saw  in  a  few  departments 
the  beginnings  of  general  managership  positions  which  could  meet  this 
need,  but  the  development  has  not  continued.  Recently  there  has  been 
some  experience  with  trying  to  solve  the  management  problem  by  ap- 
pointing career  administrators  to  assistant  secretaryships  or  undersecre- 
taryships  of  departments,  positions  traditionally  occupied  by  political 
appointees.  There  is  not  yet  a  consensus  on  the  best  solution. 

(^Separation  of  responsibilities  for  policy  initiative  and  general  manage- 
ment presents  obvious  practical  advantages  on  appropriate  levels  of  action. 
There  is  something  to  be  said  for  the  view  that  further  advancement  in 
public  administration  depends  in  some  measure  on  the  possibility  of  a  more 
extensive  employment  of  the  formula  behind  it.  Yet  in  all  the  cases  here 

1  See  his  report  entitled  "Federal  Administrative  Management,  1932-1942,"  Transactions 
of  the  American  Society  of  Mechanical  Engineers,  1943,  Vol.  65,  p.  242  ff.  The  question  of 
providing  for  a  general  manager  or  business  manager  in  the  departmental  framework  has 
nothing  to  do,  of  course,  with  the  distinction  between  staff  and  line.  See  above  Ch.  7,  "Work- 
ing Concepts  of  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Line  and  Staff." 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  16 1 

cited  the  distinction  between  political  head  and  administrative  manager 
is  sharper  in  name  than  it  is  in  fact.(jThe  separation  of  these  roles  is  suc- 
cessful only  where  the  relationships  between  the  officials  are  characterized 
by  mutual  confidence— confidence  sustained  through  frequent  conference 
and  counsel.  V  The  practical  working  arrangements  between  the  two  will 
vary  somewhat  from  jurisdiction  to  jurisdiction.LTheir  net  result  in  every 
case  should  be  such  a  modification  of  the  functional  separation  as  to  pro- 
duce, in  Bagehot's  phrase,  an  "intimate  detachment"  between  the  two  officers' 
— like  that  between  the  British  minister  and  his  permanent  undersecretary/ 

Combination  of  Political  Leadership  and  Administration.  Having 
acknowledged  the  fact  of  instances  of  bifurcation  even  in  government,  we 
may  return  to  the  general  rule:  combination  of  policy  initiative  and  top 
management  in  a  single  official  known  as  the  chief  executive,  who  is  sub- 
ject to  legislative  control.  This  is  the  principal  clue  to  the  nature  of  the 
office  of  President — and,  on  their  own  planes,  the  offices  of  governor  and 
mayor.  Each  serves  simultaneously  as  political  leader  and  administrative 
chief.  The  powers  and  prerogatives  of  their  offices  may  be  inadequate  to 
the  double  task;  yet  they  are  supposed  to  be  effective  in  both  capacities.  As 
for  the  handicaps  under  which  they  may  have  to  labor,  they  are  expected 
to  surmount  them  or  contrive  to  reduce  their  ill  effects. 

Every  one  of  our  presidents  since  John  Adams  has  realized  that  no  one 
could  hope  to  be  a  successful  leader  of  national  policy  if  he  did  not  first 
succeed  in  being  the  effective  leader  of  his  own  political  party.  On  the 
administrative  side,  nearly  every  president — at  least  since  Theodore  Roose- 
velt—has shown  himself  aware  of  the  need  for  better  managerial  arrange- 
ments to  facilitate  executive  leadership  and  has  tried  to  obtain  such 
arrangements. 

In  the  states  and  cities,  developments  have  been  been  roughly  parallel. 
Governors  and  mayors  have  long  recognized  the  indispensability  of  organ- 
ized support  among  the  voters  in  order  to  be  influential  in  making  or 
changing  public  policy.  Generally  speaking,  however,  it  has  only  been 
since  the  first  practical  tests  in  1917  of  state  administrative  reorganiza- 
tion that  governors  have  begun  to  be  comparably  effective  as  administrative 
chiefs.  Even  now,  nearly  half  of  the  states  are  still  substantially  untouched 
by  this  movement.2  As  for  mayoral  chief  executives,  in  most  cases  they 
are  unable  to  measure  up  to  the  expectations  held  for  them  as  adminis- 
trators until  the  municipality  has  revised  its  charter  with  the  intent  of 
adopting  the  so-called  strong-mayor  form  of  city  government.  Many  Ameri- 
can cities,  particularly  those  with  larger  populations,  have  effected  such  re- 
visions. However,  there  remain  hundreds  upon  hundreds  of  communities 

2  Lipson,  Leslie  M.,  The  American  State  Governor:  From  Figurehead  to  Leader,  Chicago: 
University  of  Chicago  Press,  1939,  probably  provides  the  best  summary  and  analysis  of  the 
position  of  the  governor  as  chief  executive  currently  available. 


L62  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

where  the  lot  of  the  municipal  executive  as  administrative  head  is  not  a 


lappy  one.3 


2.  LEADERSHIP  AND  AUTHORITY 


Cloa\  of  Legal  Power.  Patently,  the  position  of  chief  executive  em- 
)odies  tremendous  responsibility  and  authority.  (However,  no  man  who 
jains  this  high  place  is  likely  to  achieve  more  than  indifferent  success  unless 
ic  conceives  his  job  first  of  all  in  terms  of  opportunity  for  lasting  accomplish- 
nent.y  That  is  the  mark  of  the  great  chief  executive  in  democratic  gov- 
ernment: he  looks  upon  his  office  as  giving  him  for  his  term  the  noblest 
assignment  within  the  power  of  the  people — the  privilege  of  making  his 
e^ership  effective  in  action  designed  to  promote  the  general  welfare. 
/vThe  greatest  of  American  presidents  and  governors  and  mayors  have 
lever  been  content  to  do  only  what  they  had  to  dpjjNor  have  they  relied 
jpon  their  legal  authority  alone  to  win  their  ends/  Although  not  unwilling 
:o  use  authority  when  obliged  to  do  so,  they  Have  always  had  clear  ideas 
about  the  uses  to  which  the  power  of  government  should  be  put,  and  have 
^referred  to  gain  their  ends  through  leadership  rather  than  through  im- 
)osition  of  constitutional  sanctions. 

(  Every  public  office  requires  a  legal  definition  of  its  competence.  Such 
definitions  have  their  merits.  They  are  valuable  for  establishing  fields  of 
recognized  jurisdiction  among  various  officers.  They  are  also  indispensable 
n  enabling  the  courts  to  decide  cases  involving  on  the  one  hand  the  duty 
:>r  discretion  of  an  administrative  official  and  on  the  other  the  right  of  a 
>rivate  citizen.  Yet  it  is  clear  that  at  the  top  of  the  administrative  hier- 
irchy  such  legal  delineations,  though  not  unnecessary,  are  in  themselves 
nsufficient  to  raise  an  official  to  the  stature  of  a  chief  executive.  Clothes 
do  not  make  the  man;  neither  do  the  vestments  of  power  make  a  president. 
Legal  authority  a  chief  executive  must  have.  However,  unless  it  is  in 
effect  a  confirmation  of  leadership  accepted  or  emerging,  the  chances  are 
:hat  it  will  profit  him  very  little.^ 

Constitutions  and  charters  invest  a  chief  executive  with  the  legal  com- 
setence  to  recommend  and  veto  legislation,  appoint  and  dismiss  subor- 
dinate officials,  orepare  and — upon  legislative  approval — execute  budgets, 
represent  the  government  at  all  manner  of  official  functions,  and  direct 
:he  entire  executive  establishment.  The  placement  of  these  several  powers 
in  his  hands  is  obviously  essential  to  the  performance  of  his  main  duties, 
but  it  is  far  from  being  all  that  is  essential.  Legal  powers  are,  so  to  speak, 
the  executive's  bones.  Flesh  and  blood,  mind  and  spirit,  he  must  supply 
bimself. 

Personal  Qualifications.   One  of  the  things  of  mind  and  spirit  the  execu- 

3  For  sound  treatments  of  the  executive  function  in  city  government,  see  Story,  Russell  M., 
The  American  Municipal  Executive,  Urbana:  University  of  Illinois,  1918,  and  Reed,  Thomas  H., 
Municipal  Management,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1941. 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  163 

tive  must  bring  to  his  job  is  strength  and  balance  of  personality.  ^Without 
the  deeper  authority  latent  in  this  resource  the  prospect  of  his  developing 
vital  relationships  will  be  almost  nil,  in  administration  as  well  as  in  politics. 
For  an  administrative  head,  it  is  one  thing  to  have  the  legal  right  to  com- 
mand; it  is  something  quite  different  to  have  effective  direction  over  an 
executive  organization.  The  former  is  a  matter  of  formal  power.  The 
latter  is  largely  a  matter  of  appeal  and  influence.  It  requires,  first  of  all, 
evidence  ofjnterest,  intelligence,  and  energy.  Unless  there  be  about  the 
executive  a  single-minde'dness  which  will  enable  him  to  generate  and  sus- 
:ain  a  general  concern  for  the  fulfillment  of  the  goals  of  his  program,  he 
cannot  hope  to  assert  the  authority  that  signifies  the  true  leader.  If  he 
does  not  care,  no  one  will  care;  there  will  be  no  program.  /  Let  him  beware 
at  all  times  of  being  content  merely  to  sit  in  the  executive's  chair;  his  job 
consists  not  of  being  but  of  doing.*  Only  if  he  demonstrates  by  continuous 
interest  that  he  has  made  the  aims  of  the  total  enterprise  his  very  own 
concern  will  he  stand  out  as  head  of  the  organization. 

Basic  intelligence — as  contrasted  with  great  learning — is  so  indispen- 
sable that  nothing  more  is  needed  here  than  the  merest  mention  of  it 
No  man  willingly  takes  suggestions — much  less  orders — from  someone 
who  is  plainly  "hard  of  thinking,"  regardless  of  how  eminent  or  exalted 
his  position.  (The  hardness  may  stem  from  deficiency  of  brain  power  or 
From  set  bias  or  from  infirmity  of  age;  it  makes  no  difference)  There  is 
no  substitute  for  the  ability  to  think.\x 

Energy  is  another  prime  necessity.  He  could  never  be  more  than  a 
lominal  executive  who,  though  showing  steady  interest  and  intelligence, 
kvas  devoid  of  physical  and  nervous  vigor.  It  is  not  surprising  that  presi- 
dents, premiers,  and  other  top  executives  find  their  tasks  a  heavy  drain 
upon  their  energies.  .-'That  is  an  inescapable  aspect  of  their  work.  There  is 
a  point  to  the  argument  that  a  man's  age  and  vigor  have  a  direct  bearing 
on  his  fitness  for  high  executive  office.  Exceptions  can  be  justified  by  ex- 
:eptional  facts,  but,  as  a  general  rule,  no  one  should  be  asked  or  expected  to 
undertake  arduous  executive  responsibilities  in  his  declining  years.  Especi- 
illy  in  the  American  presidency,  the  risks  to  the  public  welfare  are  too 
great  in  an  era  when  government  must  play  so  positive^a  role  in  support 
Df  the  social  order.%>) 

These  qualities  are  fundamental  to  strength  of  personality.  (JBut  they 
must  also  be  in  balance.  )Unless  the  individual's  traits  are  so  combined 
that  they  will  enable  him  to  win  and  hold  the  devotion  of  other  men,  he 
has  little  chance  of  meeting  the  demands  made  on  the  executive  office. 
Others  must  be  able  to  feel  that  they  know  him  and  can  trust  him,  be- 
cause he  is  regarded  as  the  captain  of  their  team.  (President  Franklin  D. 
Roosevelt  epitomized  the  right  point  of  view  at  his  first  inaugural:  "For 
the  trust  reposed  in  me  I  will  return  the  courage  and  the  devotion  that 
befit  the  time.  I  can  do  no  less.  .  .  .  The  people  of  the  United  States  .  .  . 


164  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

have  made  me  the  present  instrument  of  their  wishes.  In  the  spirit  of  the 
gift  I  take  it/0 

Marf(  of  Leadership.  More  specifically,  an  executive  must  have  that 
quality  about  his  whole  personality  which  enables  him,  without  sacrificing 
integrity  of  purpose,  to  lubricate  human  relationships*  \It  is  this  influence 
that  prompts  men  to  prefer  action  based  on  their  big  agreements  to  endless 
argument  over  their  little  differences.)  It  is  this  influence  that  induces  them 
to  retain  their  enthusiasm  for  a  general  program  even  after  it  has  become 
clear  that  they  are  not  going  to  be  able  to  "have  things  exactly  their  own 
way.'*  |  The  chief  executive  can  have  high  self-confidence,  but  only  if  his 
identification  with  the  entire  administrative  undertaking  is  so  complete 
that  those  around  him  will  take  his  sureness  as  proof  of  a  conviction  that 
"Together  we  can  and  will  do  it!"  Probably  General  Eisenhower  rose  to 
as  nearly  perfect  an  identity  of  individuality  and  program  during  the  war  in 
Europe  as  has  been  reached  by  any  great  executive  in  recent  years.  The 
seal  of  that  perfection  lay  in  his  being  even  more  ready  to  take  the  blame 
when  things  went  wrong  than  to  accept  the  glory  when  victory  crowned 
the  efforts  of  his  soldiers  and  his  staff.  To  be  truly  effective,  says  Urwick 
in  his  Elements  of  Administration,4  "command  must  represent  a  common 
objective."  Whether  or  not  it  achieves  this  depends  primarily  upon  the 
spirit  that  emanates  from  the  commander's  personality. 

Someone  has  defined  leadership  as  the  ability  to  make  other  men  "feel 
two  inches  higher."  The  observation  applies  to  administrative  leadership 
as  much  as  to  any  other  kind.  The  greatest  executives  are  always  marked 
by  a  generosity  of  attitude  toward  those  under  them,  by  a  willingness  to 
overstate  rather  than  understate  their  subordinates'  accomplishments,  par- 
ticularly when  it  comes  to  the  assessment  of  credits  and  honors.  The  toast 
which  Joseph  Stalin  offered  at  the  victory  celebration  in  the  Kremlin  on 
June  25,  1945,  for  example,  affords  some  insight  into  the  executive  qualities 
of  this  leader:5 

(Do  not  expect  me  to  say  anything  extraordinary.  I  have  a  most  simple 
and  ordinary  toast  to  propose. 

I  should  like  to  drink  the  health  of  the  people  of  whom  few  hold  ranks 
and  whose  titles  are  not  envied,  people  who  are  considered  to  be  cogs 
in  the  wheels  of  the  great  State  apparatus,  but  without  whom  all  of  us 
— marshals,  front  and  army  commanders — are,  to  put  it  crudely,  not 
worth  a  tinker's  damn.  One  of  the  cogs  goes  out  of  commission — and 
the  whole  thing  is  done  for. 

I  propose  a  toast  for  simple,  ordinary,  modest  people,  for  those  cogs 
who  keep  our  great  State  machine  going  in  all  the  branches  of  science, 
national  economy  and  military  affairs.  There  are  very  many  of  them, 
their  name  is  legion — they  are  tens  of  millions  of  people. 

They  are  modest  people.  Nobody  writes  anything  about  them.  They 

4  Urwick,  Lyndall,  The  Elements  of  Administration,  p.  80,  New  York:  Harper,  1943. 

5  Information  Bulletin,  Embassy  of  the  Union  of  Soviet  Socialist  Republics  in  Washington, 
July  12,  1945. 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  165 

have  no  titles  and  few  of  them  hold  ranks.  But  they  are  the  people  who 
support  us,  as  the  base  supports  the  summit. 

I  drink  to  the  health  of  these  people— our  respected  comrades. 

One  other  basic  element  iri  administrative  leadership  remains  to  be 
mentioned.  It  is  the  most  important  of  all.)  That  is  the  talent  for  ideas, 
the  ability  to  conceive  solutions  to  current  political,  economic,  and  social 
problems  which  the  public  will  approve,  or,  at  the  least,  can  be  persuaded 
to  accept.  In  the  final  analysis,  a  chief  executive  succeeds  or  fails  in  terms 
of  the  substantive  policies  he  espouses — and  if  he  espouses  none  he  is  not  a 
chief  executive.  No  matter  what  other  qualifications  a  man  may  possess, 
if  he  lacks  the  capacity  for  initiating  concrete  proposals  to  meet  the  urgent 
issues  of  his  day,  he  has  no  warrant  for  seeking  or  accepting  executive 
office.  Nor  is  he  likely  to  gain  such  office  if  he  has  to  win  his  way  in  an 
election  against  someone  who  does  have  positive  ideas  to  offer. 

Political  and  Administrative  Talent.  Anybody  can  rant  about  the  need 
for  efficiency  and  economy  in  government.  Every  normally  articulate  ad- 
ministrator inveighs  against  unnecessary  overlapping  and  duplication.  No 
ordinarily  alert  official  has  yet  been  found  who  has  denied  the  need  for 
coordination  and  cooperation  among  governmental  agencies.  But  these  are 
not  policy  issues.^  They  are  standards,  and  they  are  universally  accepted. 
Up  to  now  no  Democrat  has  been  caught  alive  who  would  admit  that  a 
Republican  could  be  more  firmly  attached  to  such  standards  than  he — 
or  vice  versa.  And  none  ever  will. 

With  respect  to  public  policies,  however,  the  situation  is  wholly  different. 
Whether  a  chief  executive  is  concerned  about  social  issues  and  willing  to 
take  a  stand  on  proposals  for  their  solution  is  something  the  electorate  can 
easily  find  out.  It  is  impossible  for  him  to  get  by  with  pretense  or  evasion, 
except  temporarily.  A  man  aspiring  to  elective  executive  office  must  be 
•prepared  to  disparage  the  claims  of  the  opposition  candidate — and  there  may 
be  times  when  this  alone  will  "put  him  in."  However,  the  fundamental 
thing  the  people  want  to  know  is  not  what  the  incumbent  has  done  wrong 
but  how  the  contender  would  do  things  differently. 

In  a  purely  administrative  or  managerial  position,  commitment  to  such 
goals  as  "economy  and  efficiency"  is  all  that  can  be  expected.  Such  rather 
mechanical  or  mathematical  virtues  plus  platform  technique  do  not  suffice 
to  make  a  president  or  a  governor.  Nor  can  a  chief  executive  worthy  of 
the  name  be  produced  by  synthetic  composition—so  much  political  leader- 
ship and  so  much  executive  ability.  The  assumption  may  have  done  him 
an  injustice,  but  Thomas  Dewey  was  handicapped  in  the  1944  presidential 
race  by  the  suspicion,  widely  entertained,  that  he  was  not  a  "natural."  Few 
of  his  critics  could  deny  that  he  appeared  to  have  made  a  good  record  "as 
an  administrator,"  yet  they  were  able  to  persuade  many  voters  that,  even 
though  he  was  efficient,  at  any  rate  he  was  "nothing  more."  Be  this  as  it 
mavJ  the  fact  remains:  over  and  above  administrative  capacity  a  chief 


166  1KB  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

executive  must  possess  talent  for  political  leadership.  If  he  has  the  latter 
in  abundance  it  may  compensate  for  deficiencies  in  the  former  because 
soundness  of  policy  generally  eases  administrative  tasks.  ff*he  rule  does 
not  apply  with  equal  force  in  reverse,  however,  because  there  is  no  substi- 
tute for  enlightened  vision.) 

American  Presidents.  From  Washington  to  Truman,  the  American 
presidency  illustrates  considerably  varying  types  of  executive  leadership. 
Among  the  thirty-two  men  who  have  occupied  the  position,  several  stand 
out  as  administrative  heads  of  extraordinary  talent.  Washington's  signal 
success  in  launching  the  new  government  is  traceable  to  his  ability  to  take 
ideas  from  both  Hamiltonian  and  Jeffersonian  sources,  weld  them  into  a 
single  program,  and  then  enlist  the  aid  of  both  factions  in  its  execution 
The  inferior  of  both  Hamilton  and  Jefferson  in  originating  plans  and  pro- 
posals, he  was  their  superior  in  devising  combinations  of  policy  on  which 
it  was  possible  to  reach  agreement  for  action.  What  made  Washington's 
leadership  acceptable  and  effective,  however,  was  not  simply  his  intelli- 
gence at  finding  high  common  denominators.  There  were  also  his  known 
competence  in  management  and  his  proven  personal  disinterestedness.  The 
secret  of  his  achievement  as  President  did  not  lie,  of  course,  in  the  legal 
authority  with  which  he  was  endowed  by  virtue  of  Article  II  of  the  Con- 
stitution. It  lay  in  the  confidence  the  public  had  learned  to  put  in  him  be- 
cause of  the  character  of  his  leadership— displayed  first  in  the  crisis  of  the 
Revolution  and  later  in  the  Critical  Period. 

In  analyzing  the  reasons  for  Jefferson's  high  stature  as  President,  we  are 
tempted  to  wonder  what  kind  of  record  his  rival  Hamilton  would  have 
made  had  he  been  elected.  The  answer  is  suggested  by  saying  that  Hamil- 
ton could  hardly  have  been  elected:  with  all  his  brilliance  he  had  too  little 
gift  for  compromise.  An  executive  he  could  have  been — and  indeed  a  very 
great  executive  he  was — but  not  a  chief  executive,  sensitive  to  working  re- 
lationships. Jefferson  did  not  begin  to  equal  Hamilton  in  sheer  admin- 
istrative skill,  but  in  the  realm  of  political  thinking  he  had  a  clear  advantage 
over  the  scintillating  New  Yorker,  especially  when  we  consider  the  nascent 
democracy  in  which  they  were  mutual  contenders  for  popular  support.  The 
fact  is  that  among  all  our  chief  executives  probably  none  accomplished  so 
much  with  such  slight  administrative  wherewithal  as  Jefferson.  His  presi- 
dency proves  as  does  no  other  the  truth  that  insofar  as  the  highest  office 
in  American  government  is  concerned,  political  ingenuity  carries  greater 
weight  than  administrative  talent. 

President  Jackson  exhibited  a  type  of  executive  personality  profoundly 
different  from  that  of  any  of  his  predecessors,  and  quite  at  variance,  too, 
with  that  of  any  occupant  of  the  White  House  since.  Considering  himself 
the  spokesman  of  the  hitherto  more  or  less  unenfranchised  common  man, 
and  particularly  of  the  rising  West,  he  took  office  with  the  conviction  that 
he  had  a  mandate  from  the  electorate  to  restore  the  government  to  the 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  167 

people.  To  him,  this  entailed  beating  back  the  growing  concentration  of 
financial  power  in  private  hands,  and  preserving  and  strengthening  the 
Union  against  all  hazards.  In  his  view,  a  president  would  be  guilty  of 
dereliction  of  duty  if  he  held  himself  under  no  higher  obligation  than  to 
furnish  Congress  with  information  on  the  state  of  the  Union  and  admin- 
ister such  laws  as  the  legislature  might  adopt.  He  saw  with  exceptional 
clarity  that  under  the  American  Constitution  effective  government  de- 
pends mainly  upon  the  chief  executive.  If  he  failed  to  offer  positive 
leadership,  no  one  else  could  substitute  for  him. 

Lincoln's  genius,  like  Jefferson's,  lay  far  more  in  the  political  than  in 
the  administrative  realm.  Where  other  men,  abler  and  more  experienced 
in  governmental  management,  lost  their  heads  and  embraced  proposals 
which  could  not  possibly  have  united  the  nation,  he  devised  a  policy  at 
once  moderate,  positive,  and  capable  of  evoking  enthusiastic  popular  sup- 
port: the  limitation  of  slavery  to  those  areas  where  it  already  existed  and 
the  preservation  of  the  Union.  His  championship  of  these  policies,  attended 
as  it  was  by  unfailing  steadiness,  humility,  and  magnanimity,  earned  for  him 
his  preeminent  rank  among  the  men  who  have  occupied  the  presidency. 

Creative  Policy  Versus  Sound  Administration.  Time  lends  a  perspective 
to  our  comments  on  the  administrations  of  Washington,  Jefferson,  Jackson, 
and  Lincoln  which  we  shall  lack  for  years  to  come  in  the  case  of  those 
who  have  lived  in  the  White  House  more  recently.  It  is  impossible  to  ap- 
praise with  equal  accuracy  the  capacities  and  accomplishments  of  Cleveland, 
Theodore  Roosevelt,  Wilson,  and  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt.  Yet  there  is 
one  thing  that  can  be  said  of  these  later  presidents  quite  as  safely  as  of  the 
earlier  ones.  They  were  distinguished  far  more  for  socially  creative  policy 
than  for  economically  efficient  administration.6 

Nor  does  the  rule  work  only  one  way.  The  national  chief  executives 
who  are  least  well  remembered  are  precisely  those  who  lacked  the  impulse 
or  the  capacity  to  be  imagiaative  about  their  office.  They  tended  to  look 
upon  their  powers  in  narrowly  legal  terms  or  seemed  unable  to  conceive 
of  any  higher  public  service  than  that  of  reducing  the  tax  rate.  Buchanan, 
Grant,  McKinley,  Harding,  and  Coolidge  rank  among  the  lesser  lights  of 
the  White  House  for  one  and  the  same  reason.  Since  they  pursued  no  dis- 

6  For  broad  verification  of  the  theses  presented  in  the  text,  see  Corwin,  Edward  S.,  The 
President:  Office  and  Powers,  New  York:  New  York  University  Press,  1940;  Laski,  Harold  J., 
The  American  Presidency.  New  York:  Harper,  1940;  Milton,  George  Fort,  The  Use  of  Presi- 
dential Power,  Boston:  Little,  Brown  &  Co.,  1944. 

The  literature  of  business  administration  is  voluminous.  For  an  analysis  of  the  more 
important  qualifications  and  functions  of  top  corporation  executives,  see  Clccton,  Glenn  W. 
and  Mason,  Charles  W.,  Executive  Ability:  Its  Discovery  and  Development,  Yellow  Springs: 
Antioch  Press,  1934;  Tead,  Ordway,  Human  Nature  and  Management,  New  York:  McGraw- 
Hill,  1938;  Barnard,  Chester  I.,  The  Functions  of  the  Executive,  Cambridge:  Harvard  Uni- 
versity Press,  1938;  Mooney,  James  D.  and  Rciley,  Alan  C.,  The  Principles  of  Organization 
New  York:  Harper,  1939. 


168  THE   CHIEF   EXECUTIVE 

tinctive  public  policies,  the  nation  has  not  been  much  interested  in  the 
economy  or  efficiency  they  achieved  in  their  administrations. 

Business  Leaders.  What  has  been  said  about  the  test  of  success  for  the 
chief  executives  of  our  national  government  is  also  borne  out  in  the  records 
of  American  business  leadership.  These  leaders,  too,  must  rely  on  their 
influence  upon  others  rather  than  on  formal  authority  if  they  are  to  rise 
to  the  heights.  By  the  nature  of  things,  to  a  greater  degree  than  in  gov- 
ernment, the  policies  of  commercial  enterprise,  in  the  sense  of  final  or  basic 
goals,  are  set  forth  in  advance.  The  objective  of  business  executives  is  to 
make  money  through  well-planned  and  efficient  production  and  sale  of 
goods  or  services.  The  more  money  they  can  make  for  their  company, 
the  greater  their  reward.  The  policy  problem  does  not  assume  for  them  the 
proportions  it  necessarily  does  in  the  case  of  governmental  chief  executives. 
With  this  significant  qualification,  the  conditions  for  executive  success  in 
both  government  and  business  are  much  the  same. 

John  D.  Rockefeller,  Andrew  Carnegie,  James  J.  Hill,  Owen  D.  Young, 
Walter  S.  Gifford,  and  Alfred  P.  Sloan  became  great  business  executives 
because  they  were  first  leaders  of  men.  The  secret  of  their  authority  among 
their  associates  and  subordinates  lay  in  the  continuous  demonstration  of 
their  superiority  in  intelligence,  in  imagination,  in  shrewdness,  in  daring, 
and  in  personal  magnetism — the  very  qualities  recognized  by  their  col- 
laborators as  most  essential  at  the  highest  rung  of  the  executive  ladder. 
True  enough,  volume  of  stock  ownership,  family  relationship,  and  per- 
sonal friendship  all  have  a  bearing  on  the  selection  of  top  officials  in  business 
corporations.  However,  at  least  among  the  larger  firms,  the  basic  criterion 
is  usually  capacity  for  leadership.  Responsibility  is  likely  to  come  to  those 
who  are  most  ready  and  anxious  to  accept  it. 

Governors  and  Mayors.  It  is  to  be  expected  that  the  relationship  be- 
tween authority  and  leadership  in  the  case  of  state  and  municipal  chief 
executives  corresponds  very  closely  with  our  findings  about  the  presidency. 
The  great  governors  have  been  the  champions  of  the  general  welfare  in 
response  to  the  vital  issues  of  their  day;  they  have  earned  less  acclaim  as 
efficient  administrators  of  established  programs.  It  does  not  alter  the  gen- 
eral fact  to  acknowledge  that  in  some  cases  their  most  singular  achievement 
has  been  to  raise  the  whole  tone  and  level  of  public  administration  for  the 
promotion  of  particular  policies.  This  has  often  been  the  necessary  pre- 
requisite to  an  attack  upon  emerging  problems  of  substantive  policy. 

LaFollette  of  Wisconsin,  Smith,  Roosevelt,  and  Lehman  of  New  York, 
Olson  and  Stassen  of  Minnesota,  Winant  of  New  Hampshire,  Murphy  of 
Michigan,  Saltonstall  of  Massachusetts,  Arnall  of  Georgia,  Warren  of  Cali- 
fornia— these  may  or  may  not  be  the  greatest  governors  to  have  held  office 
in  our  day.  But  they  are  among  the  elect.  And  in  every  instance,  their 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  169 

reputation  has  turned  on  political  leadership  rather  than  on  administrative 


attainment.7 


Generally  speaking,  policy  issues  on  the  municipal  level  hold  rela- 
tively less  importance  than  on  the  state  level — and  considerably  less 
.han  on  the  national  plane.  Despite  this  fact,  the  prestige  of  a  municipal 
^hief  executive  still  depends  mainly  on  the  kind  of  program  he  sponsors 
and  the  dynamic  qualities  of  his  personality.8  LaGuardia  in  New  York 
City,  Hoan  in  Milwaukee,  Seasongood  in  Cincinnati,  Maverick  in  San 
Antonio,  Wyatt  in  Louisville,  and  Lausche  in  Cleveland — none  of  these 
distinguished  mayors  has  contented  himself  with  being  merely  a  faithful 
steward  of  "things  as  he  found  them."  On  the  contrary,  all  have  carried 
forward  new  programs  supplementing  or  supplanting  the  old — programs 
that  held  the  promise  of  making  for  better  community  life  rather  than 
merely  more  efficient  administration.9 

3.   EXTERNAL  RELATIONSHIPS 

The  chief  executive's  relations  with  individuals  and  groups  outside  the 
executive  branch  are  bound  to  absorb  much  of  his  time  and  energy  regard- 
less of  whether  the  form  of  government  be  presidential  or  parliamentary. 
However,  given  the  separation  of  powers  and  the  traditions  attendant  upon 
it  in  the  United  States,  such  external  relations  can  hardly  fail  to  be  of 
the  keenest  and  most  continupys  concern  to  the  head  of  the  administrative 
machinery  of  government.  Within  the  governmental  framework  itself  his 
responsibilities  are  three.  He  must  establish  and  maintain  good  relations 
with  the  legislature,  with  the  judiciary,  and — depending  upon  the  circum- 
stances— with  other  chief  executives.  It  will  be  useful  to  look  at  each  ot 
these  separately. 

Relations  with  the  Judiciary.  Ordinarily,  executive-judicial  relationships 
are  not  especially  problematical.  Assuming  that  the  measures  a  chief  execu- 
tive has  in  mind  to  propose  for  legislative  action  do  not  raise  issues  of 
constitutionality  in  terms  of  court  precedents  and  general  judicial  disposi- 
tion, he  should  have  little  difficulty  in  living  in  peace  with  the  judiciary. 
Prudent  use  of  his  power  of  appointment  will  pay  dividends,  even  though 


7  See  the  pointed  exchange  of  views  "On  Governors"  between  Leonard  D.  White  and 
Frank  Bane  in  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  68  ff.f  153  ff. 

8  There  are  those  who  argue  that  the  policy  element  in  city — and  even  in  state — govern- 
ment is  not  large  enough  to  sustain  by  itself  partisan  elections.   Suffice  it  to  observe  that,  even 
after  allowing  for  some  diminution  on  the  local  level  as  compared  with  the  two  higher  levels, 
there  is  enough  policy  substance  remaining  to  make  the  reputation  of  municipal  chief  executives 
turn  chiefly  upon  what  they  stand  for  in  politics. 

9  We  can  gain  a  good  understanding  of  the  qualities  needed  in  the  mayoralty  from  such 
volumes  as  these:   Rankin,  Rebecca,  ed.,  New  Yor%  Advancing,  New  York:   Municipal  Refer- 
ence Library,  1945;  Hoan,  Daniel  W.,  City  Government,  New  York:  Harcourt,  Brace  &  Co., 
1936;  Merriam,  Charles  E.,  Chicago:   A  More  Intimate  View  of  Urban  Politics,  New  York: 
Macmillan,  1929;  Whitlock.  Brand,  Forty  Years  of  It,  New  York:  Appleton,  rev.  cd.,  1925. 


170  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

in  the  federal  government  opportunity  for  nomination?  is  controlled  by 
death,  retirement,  or  resignation  from  the  bench. 

However,  as  the  epic  battle  in  1937  between  the  Supreme  Court  and 
Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  demonstrated,  a  "strong  man"  in  the  presidency 
is  apt  not  only  to  bring  forward  new  ideas  and  programs  but  also  for  this 
very  reason  to  run  up  against  the  latent  conservatism  of  the  judiciary.  In 
such  a  situation,  matters  do  not  simply  resolve  themselves  through  the 
President's  appointive  power,  because  vacancies  on  the  bench  may  be  slow 
to  occur.  There  is,  in  fact,  no  readily  available  constitutional  mechanism 
for  attaining  constructive  adjustment  under  these  conditions.  The  only 
remedy  lies  in  the  President's  hold  on  popular  support.  Not  even  the 
Supreme  Court  can  afford  to  stand  between  a  resourceful  national  leader 
and  the  majority  of  the  people. 

Relations  with  the  Legislature.  In  his  relations  with  the  legislature,  the 
chief  executive  faces  a  different  situation.  Both  the  legislative  and  executive 
branches  have  political  functions  to  perform.  Unless  they  see  generally 
eye  to  eye  with  each  other  on  the  need  for  public  action,  government  may 
simply  have  to  mark  time.  And  not  merely  that.  Through  its  power  of 
sanction  over  policy  proposals  requiring  statutory  enactment,  its  control  over 
liie  public  purse,  and  its  confirmation  of  major  appointments  by  the  upper 
chamber,  the  legislature  can  do  much  to  facilitate  or  obstruct  day-by-day 
administration.  What  this  adds  up  to  is  that  presidents,  governors,  and 
mayors  must  get  along  with  their  legislative  assemblies  not  just  occasionally 
but  continuously.  This  is  true  despite  the  fact  that,  by  proclaiming  the 
separation  and  independence  of  powers,  the  Constitution,  together  with  the 
general  tradition  born  of  it,  encourages  each  branch  of  government  to  be 
constantly  sensitive  about  the  recognition  of  its  prerogatives  and  its 
coordinate  position. 

The  prospect  of  effective  government  under  these  circumstances  depends 
upon  several  considerations,  each  of  which  the  chief  executive  must  exploit 
to  full  advantage.  In  the  first  place,  he  can  capitalize  on  the  fact  that  in  the 
United  States,  notwithstanding  the  forces  of  pressure  politics,  there  is  a 
wide  consensus  on  the  principle  of  the  priority  of  the  publig_jKelfare  over 
private  interests.  Thus  he  is  able  to  frame  and  present  his  proposals  for 
national  measures  in  terms  of  that  consensus.  Secondly,  by  virtue  of  his 
role  as  the  leader  of  his  party,  he  can  appeal  in  the  name  of  the  party  and 
its  platform  for  support  of  his  program  from  all  members  of  the  party  in 
the  legislative  branch.  In  the  third  place,  he  has  opportunities  to  demon- 
strate the  depth  and  sincerity  of  his  desire  for  cooperation  with  the  legislature 
by  showing  at  all  times  a  generous  respect  for  its  high  place  in  the  grand 
scheme  of  democracy,  and  by  collaborating  with  its  leaders  to  create  chan- 
nels and  arrangements  for  full  and  frequent  consultation  on  matters  of 
mutual  concern.  Lastly,  he  can  try,  in  a  manner  designed  to  avoid  the 
appearance  of  organizing  pressure,  to  use  the  public  interest  attaching  to 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  171 

his  office  for  generating  among  the  people  a  climate  of  opinion  that  will 
dispose  both  branches  of  government  toward  a  common  approach  to  the 
solution  of  the  problems  of  the  day.  We  may  think  of  "fireside  chats" 
broadcast  nationally,  press  conferences,  and  the  like.  We  should  think  also 
of  much  hard  bargaining  behind  the  scenes. 

Agency  Contacts  with  Legislators.  It  may  be  noted  in  this  connection 
that  every  major  administrative  agency  has  its  own  contacts  with  the  legis- 
lature. These  relations,  typically  with  a  legislative  committee  or  individual 
members,  inevitably  have  a  bearing  on  the  way  in  which  the  chief  execu- 
tive gets  along  with  the  legislative  assembly  as  a  whole.  Indeed,  in  the 
national  government  the  impact  of  agency-congressional  relationships  upon 
the  President's  success  in  redeeming  his  campaign  pledges  and  giving  effect 
to  his  program  is  considerable.  Alert  courtesies  extended  by  administrative 
agencies  to  Senators  and  Representatives,  including  prompt  supply  of  tech- 
nical information  and  special  attention  to  the  needs  of  particular  con- 
stituents, can  do  much  to  create  a  general  good  will  on  the  part  of  the 
Congress  toward  "the  Administration." 

On  the  other  hand,  these  relations  may  have  another  aspect,  and  one 
grimly  detrimental  from  the  President's  standpoint.  Agency  officials  have 
sometimes  been  known  to  form  understandings  with  members  of  Congress 
that  almost  amount  to  defensive  alliances  against  the  fulfillment  of  certain 
portions  of  the  chief  executive's  program.  Obviously  no  president  can  be 
indifferent  to  the  evils  of  such  a  situation.  Yet  he  may  not  be  in  a  position 
to  correct  it  with  ease.  For  if  the  uncooperative  agency  official  has  strong 
backing  "on  the  Hill"  or  from  organized  groups  having  the  ear  of  influential 
elements  in  the  legislature,  he  becomes  virtually  untouchable.  The  chief 
executive's  only  recourse  is  to  try  to  outmaneuver  or  isolate  the  insubordi- 
nate subordinate.  To  this  extent,  administrative  hierarchy  may  break  down. 
Nor  is  the  legislative  majority  better  able  to  check  its  own  entrenched 
minorities  in  such  dealings. 

Relations  with  Other  Chief  Executives.  When  it  comes  to  his  relations 
with  other  men  of  his  own  official  status,  the  chief  executive  will  find  them 
light  or  burdensome  depending  largely  on  the  governmental  level  of  his 
job.  In  our  time,  the  President  has  few  responsibilities  more  engrossing  than 
those  involved  in  the  conduct  of  foreign  affairs.  Increasingly,  foreign  policy 
points  toward  his  own  working  relations  with  the  heads  of  other  national 
governments,  particularly  those  with  basic  international  interests  akin  to 
ours.  Even  when  his  foreign  policy  steers  through  clear  waters,  these 
relations  are  apt  to  absorb  more  of  his  time  and  thought  than  those  with 
all  the  state  governors  and  municipal  executives  put  together.  Nor  are 
they  likely  to  require  less  attention  in  the  foreseeable  future.  In  the  after- 
math of  World  War  II  we  know  that  the  victory  we  have  won  at  such 
great  cost  can  be  made  secure  only  through  a  cooperative  peace.  There  is 
probably  no  standard  by  which  presidents  and  contenders  for  the  presidency 


172  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

will  be  measured  more  sharply  than  that  of  their  standing  and  their  influ- 
ence, actual  or  potential,  in  the  international  sphere. 

Governors  and  mayors,  in  dealing  with  the  chief  executives  of  other 
governmental  jurisdictions,  rarely  confront  issues  as  important  as  those 
faced  by  the  President.  In  the  nature  of  our  governmental  tradition,  there 
are  not  as  many  working  contacts  between  governors  and  mayors  as  might 
benefit  their  public  business.  On  the  whole,  a  mayor's  relations  with  other 
chief  executives  are  likely  to  be  confined  to  conferences  on  mutual  problems 
with  the  mayors  of  neighboring  cities,  and  to  his  participation  with  other 
mayors  in  the  activities  of  his  state's  league  of  municipalities  and  either  the 
American  Municipal  Association  or— in  the  case  of  our  metropolitan  cities— 
the  United  States  Conference  of  Mayors.  As  for  the  governor,  he  will  have 
his  main  dealings  with  the  governors  of  adjoining  states  and  with  the  may- 
ors of  his  state's  largest  cities.  On  other  than  matters  of  party  politics  his 
contacts  with  the  mayors  of  other  cities  or  with  the  governors  of  more  dis- 
tant states  will  be  normally  quite  infrequent,  except  for  those  related  to 
the  Governors'  Conference  or  the  Council  of  State  Governments. 

Relations  with  Political  Parties.  We  may  turn  now  to  the  chief  execu- 
tive's external  relations  outside  the  structure  of  government  proper.  Here 
his  problems  fall  again  into  several  classes.  In  point  of  importance,  party 
relationships  probably  rank  first.  For  it  is  a  plain  fact  that  his  strength 
within  his  party,  and  in  turn  the  party's  strength  within  the  electorate,  are 
at  the  very  core  of  his  effectiveness  as  chief  executive.  Both  aspects  he  must 
cultivate  steadily.  It  therefore  behooves  him  to  counsel  frequently  with  the 
leaders  of  his  party,  to  keep  the  party  united  and  aggressive,  and  so  to  guide 
its  fortunes  that  it  may  win  and  hold  the  favor  of  the  voters. 

He  may  count  himself  fortunate  if  without  inordinate  anguish  of  soul 
he  can  handle  the  distribution  of  public  honors  and  political  appointments 
in  a  way  that  serves  his  ends.  The  management  of  these  matters  makes 
up  a  large  segment  of  what  may  be  called  party  business.  Despite  the  help 
furnished  traditionally  by  the  Postmaster  General  and  the  regular  party 
machinery,  "the  Chief"  must  give  his  own  time  to  many— sometimes  trivial- 
seeming — items.  He  must  also  be  available  for  advice  on  questions  of  party 
finance  or  even  on  the  times  and  places  of  major  party  rallies  and  radio  pro- 
grams, to  say  nothing  of  party  conventions  and  their  agenda.  Nor  should 
we  overlook  the  demands  on  him  for  securing  as  much  cooperation  as  is 
attainable  from  the  opposition  party— or  from  disaffected  elements  within 
his  own  party. 

Public  Opinion  and  Interest  Groups.  Because  of  the  cardinal  role  of 
free  means  of  mass  communication  in  democratic  government,  the  Presi- 
dent's relations  with  the  press— as  likewise  those  of  a  governor  or  a  mayor- 
are  of  peculiar  significance.  Nothing  is  more  essential  to  his  success  than 
that  he  keep  in  touch  with  the  people.  Newspapers,  magazines,  the  radio, 
and  the  moving  pictures  are  the  main  two-way  facilities  which  make  close 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  173 

contact  possible.  An  efficient  and  tactful  press  secretary  will  rank  among 
his  most  indispensable  personal  aides. 

Even  with  the  ablest  assistance,  however,  the  President  will  be  obliged 
to  give  personal  attention  to  what  publicity  he  wants  and  what  political  in- 
telligence services  he  needs.  It  goes  without  saying  that  insofar  as  his 
direct  use  of  the  various  media  is  concerned,  he  is  wise  to  make  the  most 
of  his  particular  gifts  of  expression  and  make  the  least  of  his  shortcomings. 
If  the  press  and  radio  and  Hollywood  take  a  friendly  line  and  he  learns 
how  to  cooperate  with  them,  they  can  do  a  great  deal  to  build  him  up  and 
keep  him  before  the  eye  of  the  public.  For,  regardless  of  what  history  may 
later  say  of  him,  here  and  now  he  will  be  what  they  say  he  is— unless  the 
next  election  shows  them  to  have  been  quite  wrong. 

Interest  groups  pose  a  tough  problem  for  every  politician  who  dedicates 
his  efforts  to  the  common  good,  whether  he  be  in  the  executive  or  legisla- 
tive branch.  The  special  interest  tends  to  assume  something  no  chief  execu- 
tive mindful  of  his  trust  would  grant— that  what  is  good  for  it  will  auto- 
matically be  good  for  all  the  people.  It  is  clear,  however,  that  he  cannot 
ignore  interest  groups  in  the  political  arena.  *  In  the  first  place,  it  is  of  the 
essence  of  democracy  that  men  should  be  free  to  associate  their  efforts  in 
promoting  interests  and  enterprises  in  which  they  share.  -Secondly,  it  is 
equally  essential  that  government  subject  the  struggle  for  power  among 
interest  groups  to  such  regulation  and  control  as  is  needed  to  safeguard  the 
public  welfare.  A  potent  factor  in  the  situation  is,  of  course,  the  powerful 
influence  interest  groups  often  exert  over  the  way  in  which  their  members 
vote.  Consequently  each  party  is  perpetually  anxious  to  win  as  much  of 
their  support  as  possible,  or  at  least  to  avoid  drawing  upon  itself  the  antag- 
onism of  those  groups  which  cannot  be  considered  as  potential  supporters. 

Business,  labor,  agriculture,  veterans,  civic  organizations,  and  professional 
patriots  probably  constitute  the  principal  interest  groups  that  presidents  and 
governors  confront.  Municipal  chief  executives  see  less  of  organized  agri- 
culture and  more  of  neighborhood  councils,  social  welfare  organizations, 
and  taxpayers  associations.  Each  of  these  groups  makes  up  a  part  of  the 
body  politic  which  it  is  the  chief  executive's  business  to  serve.  The  great 
public  which  he  likes  to  regard  as  his  principal  too  often  turns  out  to  be 
nothing  more  than  a  loose  composite  of  little  or  lesser  publics — somehow 
bound  together  by  a  not  always  very  sharp  sense  of  larger  unity.  If  he 
can  consolidate  the  sense  of  community — a  critical  part  of  his  job — the 
various  groups  may  be  induced  to  keep  their  selfish  impulses  under  reason- 
able restraint  and  so  be  able  to  make  positive  contributions  to  the  proper 
functioning  of  government.  If  he  fails  in  this  greatest  assignment  as  a  result 
of  personal  weakness  or  of  circumstances  beyond  the  power  even  of  a  true 
leader,  he  will  learn  at  first  hand  what  havoc  pressure  politics  may  cause. 


174  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

4.  INTERNAL  DIRECTION  AND  CONTROL 

The  preceding  section,  treating  as  it  did  of  external  relationships,  dealt 
principally  with  the  political  aspects  of  the  role  of  the  chief  executive.  In 
this  and  the  succeeding  section,  an  effort  will  be  made  to  describe  the  func- 
tions he  performs  and  the  facilities  he  uses  within  the  executive  branch 
itself,  the  presidency  being  taken  as  prototype. 

Administrative  Planning  and  Direction.  As  administrator-in-chief,  the 
President's  first  task  is  to  decide  what  kind  of  general  framework  of  con- 
sensus he  may  assume  or  evolve  between  himself  and  the  legislature,  what 
are  to  be  the  main  aims  of  his  administration,  and  by  what  basic  policies  he 
will  work  for  their  attainment.  Such  anticipations  are  subject  to  change; 
yet  he  needs  some  point  of  departure.  Next,  he  must  arrange  for  plans  to 
be  developed  analyzing  specific  problem  areas  and  outlining  alternative 
methods  of  solution.  He  must  also  give  thought  to  an  organizational  struc- 
ture fitting  the  logic  of  his  aims,  policies,  and  plans.  All  of  this  requires  a 
reliable  supporting  cast. 

One  of  the  President's  principal  responsibilities  is  to  select  the  men  and 
women  who  as  agency  heads  will  fill  the  major  executive  positions  within 
his  organization.  They  in  turn  will  have  to  be  depended  upon  to  nominate 
subordinate  political  officials.  Selection  and  appointment  of  key  officers 
are,  however,  still  in  the  category  of  mere  preliminaries.  All  of  the  subordi- 
nate heads  have  to  be  directed  to  their  tasks;  it  falls  to  the  chief  executive 
to  convey  to  them  a  clear  conception  of  their  missions  in  the  government- 
wide  context. 

He  must  require  annually  of  each  agency  a  systematic  work  program 
supported  by  estimates~-of  expenditures.  In  order  to  develop  a  balanced  and 
administratively  feasible  program  for  the  executive  branch  as  a  whole, 
he  needs  to  integrate  the  agency  programs  into  a  single  comprehensive 
plan.  This  is  known  as  the  annual  budget.  No  recurrent  document  he 
submits  to  the  legislature  is  of  greater  importance.  Upon  its  presentation 
to  Congress  in  justification  of  requests  for  funds  it  is  scrutinized  by  the 
Appropriations  Committee  of  each  chamber.  Its  subsequent  adoption  by 
the  legislature,  usually  with  considerable  modifications,  translates  the 
budget  into  the  means  whereby  the  President  can  assure  himself  systemati- 
cally that  the  approved  work  plan  of  the  government  is  being  accomplished. 

Executive  Coordination  and  Administrative  Reporting.  Even  with  rea- 
sonably clear  policies  and  plans,  a  satisfactory  scheme  of  organization,  able 
top  personnel,  foresighted  direction  in  individual  agencies,  and  careful 
programming  and  scheduling  of  administrative  activities,  there  is  no  fool- 
proof guarantee  that  everything  and  everybody  will  mesh  nicely  so  that 
each  agency  can  be  left  to  run  by  itself.  One  of  the  President's  most  com- 
plicated functions  is  that  of  coordinating  the  efforts  and  operations  of  the 
entire  executive  branch.  Of  course,  the  budget  itself  is  an  instrument  of 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  175 

coordination.  Through  it  the  President  may  even  attain  a  degree  of  con- 
certed action  on  the  part  of  the  great  regulatory  boards  and  commissions 
that  in  all  other  respects,  except  for  his  power  of  appointment,  are  not  under 
his  command.  Considering  the  national  proclivity  for  agencies  which  are  in- 
dependent of  the  chief  executive,  and  a  tradition  of  rugged  administrative 
individualism  even  within  the  executive  branch  proper,  it  should  be  easy 
to  understand  that  coordination  of  governmental  activities,  week  in  and 
week  out,  is  a  heavy  responsibility  and  a  never-ending  one. 

Finally,  the  President  must  constantly  keep  his  eyes  on  the  total  admin- 
istrative picture.  He  must  make  himself  a  central  point  of  reporting.  The 
budget  provides  the  basis  for  a  systematic  gathering  and  analysis  "of  informa- 
tion. However,  the  President  needs  additional  channels  of  intelligence  about 
the  status  of  administrative  progress.  He  must  be  able  to  find  out  what 
he  should  know  in  order  to  report  effectively  to  Congress,  the  press,  or 
the  public.  This  calls  for  special  arrangements  to  provide  him  with  the  kind 
and  quantity  of  information  he  wants,  when  he  wants  it. 

Constitutional  Supports.  These  being  the  President's  main  administra- 
tive functions,  what  specific  powers  and  devices  does  he  rely  upon  to  exe- 
cute them  ?  His  prerogative  in  the  field  of  policy  initiative  derives  from  that 
clause  in  Article  II  of  the  Constitution  which  provides  that  he  "shall  from 
time  to  time  give  to  the  Congress  information  of  the  state  of  the  Union, 
and  recommend  to  their  consideration  such  measures  as  he  shall  judge 
necessary  and  expedient."  In  proposing  public  policy,  no  chief  executive 
would  want  to  act  on  the  spur  of  the  moment.  He  naturally  welcomes 
ideas  and  suggestions,  formal  and  informal,  from  a  wide  variety  of  sources 
inside  and  outside  government.  These,  however,  have  to  be  sifted  and 
evaluated;  and  a  final  selection  has  to  be  made.  Most  of  the  sifting  and 
appraising  can  be  entrusted  to  his  permanent  staff  establishments.  Often, 
however,  even  after  they  have  done  their  best,  he  will  still  need  help  in 
"making  up  his  mind."  He  may  put  the  matter  to  the  Cabinet  or  consult 
with  individual  members.  He  may  call  in  the  leaders  of  Congress.  Or  he 
may  seek  the  confidential  counsel  of  a  Colonel  House  or  a  Harry  Hopkins. 
There  is  perhaps  undue  fluidity  in  this  pattern,  but  without  a  more  highly 
developed  presidential  secretariat  we  can  hardly  expect  a  material  change. 

No  provision  in  the  Constitution  specifically  requires  or  authorizes  the 
President  in  so  many  words  to  "plan"  his  general  program.  Yet  his  need 
and  right  to  do  so  would  appear  to  be  implied  in  the  constitutional  provi- 
sion that  "he  shall  take  care  that  the  laws  be  faithfully  executed,"  and  in 
another  clause  appearing  earlier  in  Article  II  that  "he  may  require  the 
opinion,  in  writing,  of  the  principal  officer  in  each  of  the  executive  depart- 
ments, upon  any  subject  relating  to  the  duties  of  their  respective  offices," 
Even  without  these  clauses,  however,  the  necessity  for  him  to  anticipate  the 
future  would  remain.  He  would  have  to  prepare  for  it  even  though  his 


176  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

authority  might  be  derived  from  "the  law  of  the  situation"10  rather  than  the 
law  of  the  Constitution. 

With  respect  to  administrative  organization,  the  President's  powers  are 
limited.  Permanent  administrative  agencies  no  less  than  the  so-called  inde- 
pendent establishments  are  the  creations  of  Congress.  None  of  them  can 
be  broken  up  or  recombined  in  different  ways  or  merged  with  other  agen- 
cies except  by  statute.  There  is  a  strong  case  to  be  made  for  investing  the 
President  with  permanent  authority  to  adapt  administrative  structure  to 
governmental  needs,  but  so  far  no  such  continuing  authority  has  ever  been 
granted.  Temporary  grants  of  specifically  circumscribed  power  to  work  out 
structural  adjustments  have  been  made  in  the  Reorganization  Acts  of  1939 
and  1945.  In  times  of  war  the  President  is  likely  to  obtain  special  authority 
of  this  kind,  such  as  the  two  War  Powers  Acts  of  World  War  II  and  the 
Overman  Act  of  World  War  I— aside  from  his  automatically  operative 
war  powers,  which  are  of  considerable  scope. 

The  power  of  appointment  and — by  implication — of  removal  is  one  of 
the  most  telling  the  chief  executive  possesses.  Article  II  of  the  Constitution 
provides  that  he 

.  .  .  shall  nominate,  and  by  and  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  the 
Senate,  shall  appoint  ambassadors,  other  public  ministers  and  consuls, 
judges  of  the  Supreme  Court,  and  all  other  officers  of  the  United  States, 
whose  appointments  are  not  herein  otherwise  provided  for,  and  which 
shall  be  established  by  law:  but  the  Congress  may  by  law  vest  the  appoint- 
ment of  such  inferior  officers,  as  they  think  proper,  in  the  President 
alone,  in  the  courts  of  law,  or  in  the  heads  of  departments." 

The  removal  power,  held  by  the  Supreme  Court  corollary  to  the  appoint- 
ing power j11  continues  to  be  extensive  but  was  definitely  qualified  in  the 
Humphrey  case.12  Corwin  summarizes  the  present  situation  in  this  way:18 

As  to  agents  of  his  own  powers,  the  President's  removal  power  is 
illimitable;  as  to  agents  of  Congress*  constitutional  powers,  Congress 
may  confine  it  to  removal  for  cause,  which  implies  the  further  right  to 
require  a  hearing  as  a  part  of  the  procedure  of  removal. 

In  the  exercise  of  his  directive  function  over  the  various  administrative 
agencies — but  not  the  independent  regulatory  boards  and  commissions — 
the  chief  executive  is  supported  by  several  provisions  of  the  Constitution, 
chiefly  by  the  very  first  sentence  of  Article  II:  "The  executive  power  shall 
be  vested  in  a  President  of  the  United  States  of  America."  That  broad 
grant  would  perhaps  have  sufficed  of  itself  to  empower  the  President  to 

10  For  the  insight  embodied  in  this  phrase,  students  of  administration  are  indebted  to  a 
brilliant — and  practical — woman,  Mary  Parker  Follett.  Sec  her  "Individualism  in  a  Planned 
Society"  in  Mctcalf,  Henry  C.  and  Urwick,  L.,  cds.  Dynamic  Administration,  New  York: 
Harper,  1942. 

U  Myers  v.  United  States,  272  U.  S.  52,  lia  (1926). 

12  295  U.  S.  602  (1935). 

13  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  6,  p.  96. 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  177 

issue  such  orders  as  he  might  find  necessary  or  expedient  in  directing  the 
administrative  operations  of  the  executive  branch.  In  addition,  however, 
certain  other  provisions  are  relevant.  Among  them  are  the  express  stipula- 
tion in  Section  2  of  the  same  article  that  he  "shall  be  commander  in  chief 
of  the  Army  and  Navy  of  the  United  States,  and  of  the  militia  of  the  several 
states,  when  called  into  the  actual  service  of  the  United  States,"  and  the 
more  general  clause,  already  cited,  that  he  "shall  take  care  that  the  laws  be 
faithfully  executed." 

However,  uncontested  authority  to  direct  the  executive  branch  proper 
does  not  ensure  informed  and  competent  direction.  The  problem  is  how  to 
make  it  effective.  One  of  the  first  needs  is  a  system  of  administrative  com- 
munication that  will  flash  up  to  the  chief  executive  the  institutional  intelli- 
gence he  requires  from  all  sectors  of  his  entire  organization,  and  simul- 
taneously will  guarantee  that  his  orders  and  his  general  line,  of  approach 
will  get  through  without  distortion  or  delay  to  those  on  the  lower  levels  of 
command. 

Statutory  Implementation.  Work  programming  and  budgeting  are  basic 
to  sound  administration,  but  the  President  has  had  the  machinery  to  per- 
form these  functions  systematically  only  for  a  bare  quarter-century.  The 
Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921  furnished  him  specialized  staff  assistance 
in  a  Bureau  of  the  Budget  operating  primarily  by  reliance  on  his  own  direc- 
tive power.14  The  administrative  histories  of  the  states  suggest  the  same 
lesson:  that  until  a  government  adopts  the  idea  of  the  executive  budget — 
and  preferably  with  the  item  veto  that  is  lacking  in  the  federal  government 
— it  is  futile  to  expect  effective  and  economical  administration.  Of  course, 
adoption  of  such  a  system  will  not  automatically  bring  anything  like  the 
administrative  millenium.  Without  it,  however,  the  gates  to  progress  will 
open  only  halfway. 

Like  the  directive  power,  of  which  it  may  be  said  to  be  a  derivative,  the 
power  to  coordinate  is  general  in  the  character  of  its  application.  It  rests 
fundamentally  upon  the  same  clauses  in  the  Constitution  listed  as  the  sources 
of  the  directive  power.  Beyond  that  it  has  been  made  explicit  in  the  Budget 
and  Accounting  Act  and  other  statutes  in  which  Congress  has  reaffirmed  the 
President's  obligation  to  unify  the  operations  of  the  various  administrative 
agencies  it  has  created.  One  notable  recent  example  is  the  Employment  Act 
of  1946,  under  which  the  President  is  to  avail  himself  of  a  new  Council  of 
Economic  Advisers  to  convey  to  the  legislature  ways  and  means  of  attaining 
maximum  employment  throughout  the  nation  by  concerted  governmental 
action. 

As  a  source  of  central  information  about  the  national  administrative 
system,  the  chief  executive  is  the  logical  agent  reporting  on  progress  of 
operations  and  policy  problems  to  Congress  or  the  public.  The  legislature 

14  Sec  Morstcin  Marx,  Fritz,  "The  Bureau  of  the  Budget:  Its  Evolution  and  Present  Role," 
American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  p.  653  ff.,  869  ff. 


178  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

usually  requires  such  reports  in  statutory  language  written  directly  into 
acts  enabling  or  directing  him  to  launch  new  undertakings.  A  good  example 
is  the  reporting  on  the  progress  of  the  lend-lease  program  during  World 
War  II.  We  may  also  think  of  the  annual  message  on  the  State  of  the  Union 
and  the  annual  budget  message.  In  1946,  both  were  combined  for  the  first 
time  in  a  single  document  because  the  two  messages  increasingly  tended  to 
deal  with  the  same  fundamental  issues  of  healthy  economic,  social,  and  fiscal 
development  of  our  national  order.  Most  other  messages  address  themselves 
to  particular  matters. 

By  far  the  larger  body  of  data  and  proposals,  however,  emerges  in 
administrative  self-reporting  within  the  executive  branch.  This  is  the 
method — and  the  only  one — by  which  the  President  can  hope  to  keep  him- 
self abreast  of  what  is  going  on  at  the  administrative  front-lines  and  what  is 
being  done  in  his  name  by  the  army  of  federal  employees  deployed  all  over 
the  country  and  our  outposts  abroad.  Without  staff  work  to  harness  this  vast 
flow  of  information,  it  could  easily  turn  into  a  destructive  torrent.  Facts, 
figures,  and  suggestions  must  be  transformed  continuously  into  information 
serviceable  to  the  chief  executive  f  on  control  purposes. 

5.  ARMS  OF  MODERN  MANAGEMENT 

Need  for  Assistance  to  the  President*  "The  President  needs  help."  So 
wrote  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management  headed  by 
Louis  Brownlow  in  its  report  submitted  January  8,  1937.  In  assigning 
functions  and  responsibilities  to  the  executive  branch  the  Constitution  and 
the  statutes  simply  ordain  that  "the  President"  shall  do  thus  and  so. 
Obviously  no  man,  whatever  his  genius,  could  personally  perform  the  many 
and  heavy  tasks  which  the  chief  executive  thus  is  obliged  to  take  on.  It 
is  to  him  in  his  institutional  capacity — to  his  office — that  the  assignments 
are  made;  and,  except  where  Congress  has  itself  fixed  the  means,  he  is 
expected,  within  the  bounds  of  statutory  authority  and  funds  appropriated, 
to  recruit,  organize,  and  direct  whatever  personnel  may  be  required  for  the 
work  to  be  accomplished. 

Here,  with  the  sole  exception  of  the  chairmanship  of  the  Council  of 
Ministers  of  the  Soviet  Union,  is  clearly  the  biggest  management  job 
in  the  world.  How  does  the  President  handle  it?  What  aides  and  facilities 
does  he  need  to  help  him  get  his  work  done?  True,  the  great  line  depart- 
ments are  the  instruments  through  which  ultimately  the  purposes  of  the 
federal  government  are  carried  into  effect.  But  what  are  the  means  by 
which  the  President  makes  sure  that  they  know  of  his  intentions  and 
expectations  and  that  he  knows  how  well  they  are  succeeding  in  their 
tasks? 

It  was  the  general  conclusion  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Management  that:  (1)  the  President  needed,  in  addition  to  his  per- 
sonal secretaries,  as  many  as  six  administrative  assistants  on  his  immediate 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  179 

White  House  staff;  (2)  in  the  tasks  of  executive  management  he  should 
have  the  assistance  of  three  main  "arms,"  one  for  planning,  one  for  budget- 
ing, and  one  for  personnel;  (3)  with  such  internal  arrangements  as  would 
meet  the  special  problems  presented  by  regulatory  commissions  and  govern- 
mental corporations,  all  line  agencies  should  be  consolidated  into  twelve 
departments,  each  headed  by  a  secretary  of  Cabinet  rank;  and  (4)  there 
should  be  a  reordering  of  the  functions  of  the  General  Accounting  Office  to 
ensure  two  things — that,  on  the  one  hand,  auditing  prior  to  spending  should 
no  longer  keep  the  wheels  of  administration  from  moving;  and  that,  on  the 
other,  the  executive  branch  should  be  made  more  effectively  accountable  to 
Congress  by  more  searching  and  more  constructive  post-auditing. 

How  fully  House  and  Senate  would  have  accepted  these  recommenda- 
tions if  President  Roosevelt  had  not  followed  their  submission  with  his 
provocative  message  on  Supreme  Court  reform,  no  one  can  say.  In  any 
event,  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  incorporated  only  part  of  the  pro- 
posed measures.  Above  all,  the  President  was  granted  six  administrative 
assistants,  and  a  legal  foundation  was  laid  for  the  establishment  of  the 
Executive  Office  of  the  President— perhaps  the  most  significant  step  .forward 
since  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921.  The  Executive  Office  was 
made  up  of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board,15  the  Bureau  of  the 
Budget,  the  Liaison  Office  for  Personnel  Management,  the  Office  of  Gov- 
ernment Reports,  and  the  Office  for  Emergency  Management.18  This  last 
division  of  the  Executive  Office  subsequently  allowed  the  President  desirable 
leeway  for  locating  in  it — even  if  by  legal  fiction — many  of  the  great  war- 
time control  agencies. 

Notwithstanding  the  later  abolition  by  act  of  Congress  of  the  National 
Resources  Planning  Board  and  the  administrative  elimination  of  the  Office 
of  Government  Reports,  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President  has  continued 
to  serve  essential  purposes.  Its  principal  remaining  element,  the  Bureau  of 
the  Budget,  has  gone  far  to  give  the  President  highly  diversified  staff  assist- 
ance. Under  the  Employment  Act  of  1946,  its  services  have  been  amplified 
by  a  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  placed  by  law  in  the  Executive  Office. 
Technically  outside  the  Executive  Office  but  in  fact  linked  to  it  have  been  two 
other  important  presidential  agencies:  the  Office  of  War  Mobilization  and 
Reconversion17  and  the  Office  of  Economic  Stabilization,  both  devoted  more 
to  policy  development  than  to  administration. 

Realigning  the  Executive  Branch.  As  to  changes  in  the  departmental 
structure,  those  authorized  under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  and  subse- 
quently adopted  in  the  form  of  presidential  "plans"  were  not  insignificant. 

18  Sec  above  Ch.  6,  "Planning  and  Administration,"  sec.  2,  "The  Machinery  for  Plan- 
ning." 

16  See  Brownlow,  Louis  and  Others,  "The  Executive  Office  of  the  President:    A  Sym- 
posium," Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  101  ff. 

17  See  above  Ch.  6,  "Planning  and  Administration,"  sec.  2,  "The  Machinery  for  Plan- 
ning." 


180  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

Yet  the  executive  branch  emerged  from  World  War  II  in  need  not  only  of 
reconversion  to  a  peacetime  basis  but  of  further  reorganization  for  the 
general  purpose  of  increasing  its  effectiveness.  Authorization  to  propose 
such  modifications — not  extending  to  certain  exempted  establishments — was 
conferred  upon  the  President  in  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1945.18  Leaving 
aside  the  point  that  authority  to  reorganize  administrative  structure  is  in 
the  nature  of  a  continuing  necessity  and  should  therefore  not  be  granted  only 
for  a  limited  time,  how  can  the  chief  executive  best  use  such  power  as  is  now 
vested  in  him?  If  he  wants  to  make  it  serve  general  needs,  he  will  try  to 
accomplish  five  main  goals. 

First,  he  will  weigh  opportunities  for  regrouping  and  consolidation 
among  and  within  line  or  operating  agencies  to  effect  better  service,  check 
duplication,  and  reduce  the  span  of  control  for  himself  and  the  departmental 
leadership.  Of  course,  this  does  not  apply  to  those  establishments  which  are 
set  apart  by  reorganization  statute.  We  may  expect  an  integration  of  the 
War  and  Navy  Departments  into  a  single  Department  of  Defense.  In 
addition,  the  President  may  find  it  possible  to  consolidate  various  agencies 
with  othjer  main  departments.  It  has  even  been  argued  that  the  number  of 
departments  can  and  should  be  reduced  to  seven.  Experience  suggests, 
however,  that  no  change  quite  so  drastic  could  win  acceptance.  Moreover, 
too  heavy  concentration  along  this  line  might  in  turn  overtax  departmental 
leadership. 

Central  Staff  Facilities.  Second,  the  President  may  want  to  reexamine 
arrangements  for  the  conduct  of  central  staff  and  auxiliary  services 
such  as  budgeting,  recruitment  and  examination  of  personnel,  in-service 
training,  purchasing,  accounting,  printing,  safety  facilities,  and  the  like. 
Here  the  aim  would  be  to  gain  for  the  federal  government  whatever 
advantages  can  be  derived  from  centralized  staff  and  housekeeping  activities, 
while  yet  leaving  in  each  department  adequate  means  as  well  as  full 
authority  and  responsibility  for  getting  its  job  done.  This  might  also  entail 
the  removal  or  mitigation  of  the  hazards  and  impediments  to  sound  manage- 
ment within  the  executive  branch  which  are  latent  in  the  opportunities  the 
General  Accounting  Office  has  of  intervening  in  an  unproductive  manner 
in  administrative  operations.  There  is  every  reason  for  insisting  on  a 
careful  audit  of  all  records  after  an  individual  administrative  transaction 
has  been  completed.  But  there  is  no  good  reason  for  the  kind  of  supervision 
by  the  Comptroller  General  as  head  of  the  General  Accounting  Office  that 
has  developed  in  federal  administration.  Ideally,  as  the  President's  Com- 
mittee on  Administrative  Management  proposed,  Congress  should  not  only 
retain  an  auditor  general  for  the  final  examination  and  certification  of 
accounts,  but  it  should  also  demand  of  him  a  truly  comprehensive  annual 

18  Again,  as  under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  the  "hard  core"  of  independent  regula- 
tory agencies  such  as  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  and  the  Securities  and  Exchange 
Commission  was  exempted,  including  the  civil  functions  of  the  Army  Corps  of  Engineers. 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  181 

report  on  the  character  of  fiscal  operations  and  the  general  performance  of 
the  executive  branch. 

Executive  Office  of  the  President.  Third,  the  President  must  consider 
again  the  adequacy  of  his  own  staff  establishments.  The  theoretical  premises 
of  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President  have  proved  sound;  and  the  Presi- 
dent needs  all  the  help  he  can  get  from  that  office.19  Increasingly  since 
1939,  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  has  grown  into  that  great  arm  of  overhead 
management  which  is  the  intent  of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act.  In 
Arthur  Macmahon's  descriptive  phrase,  the  bureau  has  become  the  "em- 
bodiment of  the  presidency"  in  federal  administration.20  Through  its 
several  divisions — Estimates,  Fiscal,  Legislative  Reference,  Administrative 
Management,  Statistical  Standards — the  chief  executive  obtains  continuing 
assistance  in  the  preparation  and  execution  of  the  annual  budget;  in  the 
clearance  and  coordination  of  agency  proposals  for  legislation  or  views  on 
pending  bills;  in  the  achievement  of  better  organization  and  management 
throughout  the  executive  branch;  in  the  coordination  of  federal  statistical 
services;  and  in  the  analysis  of  government-wide  or  departmental  programs, 
of  issues  or  implications  of  fiscal  policy,  and  of  the  progress  of  administrative 
operations.21 

The  situation  is  different  with  regard  to  forward-looking  policy  plan- 
ning. Harried  as  the  President  tends  to  be  by  immediate  concerns,  he  re- 
quires first-rate  advice  if  he  is  to  think  wisely — or  think  at  all — about  the 
state  of  the  Union  a  decade  or  generation  hence  instead  of  a  year  or  two. 
There  was  provision  for  that  kind  of  help  as  long  as  the  National  Resources 
Planning  Board  was  still  in  existence.  Since  1943,  when  Congress  cut  off  its 
appropriations,  it  has  been  necessary  for  the  President  to  rely  on  catch-as- 
catch-can  planning  services  wherever  he  could  get  them,  even  if  only  in  bits. 
Criticisms  of  the  reconversion  program  have  time  and  again  shown  up  the 
unwisdom  of  abolishing  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board.  Sooner 
or  later,  its  equivalent  will  have  to  be  reestablished.  Perhaps  the  new  statu- 
tory Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  set  up  in  the  Executive  Office  of  the 
President  by  the  Employment  Act  of  1946,  will  eventually  develop  into 
such  an  equivalent. 

The  case  for  a  director  of  personnel  to  give  the  President  expert  counsel 
and,  as  civil  service  administrator,  to  direct  the  operations  of  the  present  Civil 
Service  Commission,  is  almost  equally  persuasive.  True,  the  present  arrange- 
ment of  a  Liaison  Office  for  Personnel  Management  within  the  Executive 

19  This  does  not  mean,  of  course,  that  there  should  be  maintained  in  the  Office  for 
Emergency  Management  skeleton  agencies  or  technical  staffs  actually  not  needed.  As  its  name 
suggests  but  docs  not  fully  explain,  this  office  serves  its  purpose  in  the  main  by  providing 
an  ever-ready  legal  and  administrative  framework  within  which  temporary  emergency  agencies 
can  be  created  when  required,  provided  that  funds  are  made  available  for  such  agencies  by 
Congress. 

^Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  "The  Future  Organizational  Pattern  of  the  Executive  Branch," 
American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1182. 

21  See  Morstcin  Marx,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  14,  p.  869  ft. 


182  THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE 

Office,  clearing  on  matters  of  presidential  interest  with  the  Civil  Service 
Commission,  has  not  been  unworkable.  Yet  it  remains  essentially  a  make- 
shift that  should  be  superseded.  The  President  is  as  much  in  need  of  having 
his  own  director  of  personnel  as  are  other  chief  executives.  Few  problems 
lie  closer  to  the  heart  of  administration  than  that  of  staffing— of  discovering, 
recruiting,  placing,  and  developing  competent  employees  so  that  they  can 
produce  at  top  capacity.  Solution  of  this  problem  should  grow  out  of  con- 
scious design  and  not  have  to  depend  upon  favorable  circumstances  in  the 
relations  between  the  President  and  a  so-called  independent  establishment, 
the  Civil  Service  Commission. 

Policy  Coordination.  The  fourth  goal  of  administrative  reorganization 
relates  to  the  equivalent  of  that  office  whose  head  used  to  be  spoken  of  as 
"Assistant  President,"  "Coordinator  of  Domestic  Affairs,"  or  "Secretary  of 
Domestic  Policy"  more  often  than  as  Director  of  War  Mobilization  and 
Reconversion.22  By  statute,  this  office  is  both  temporary  and  outside  the 
Executive  Office  of  the  President.  If  the  President  needs  a  special  staff  officer 
to  coordinate  domestic  policy,  much  as  the  Secretary  of  State  oversees 
foreign  affairs,  he  would  be  well  advised  to  place  such  an  aide  and  his  staff 
in  the  Executive  Office— as  exponent  of  directive  coordination,  in  com- 
parison with  the  functions  of  managerial  coordination  that  are  being  dis- 
charged by  the  budget  director.23  If  this  were  done,  it  would  be  possible  at 
the  same  time  to  carry  further  the  institutionalization  of  the  Executive  Office. 
It  still  needs  better  inner  balance  of  policy  development  and  administrative 
concerns;  better  integration  of  its  working  processes,  including  the  White 
House  staff  in  the  technical  sense;  and  better  facilities  for  checking  back  and 
forth  on  all  matters  that  come  to  the  President's  desk. 

Potentialities  of  the  Cabinet.  The  fifth  and  final  goal  for  which  the 
President  should  strive  as  part  of  any  reorganization  is  to  make  greater  use 
of  his  underdeveloped  Cabinet.  Ample  delegation  of  authority  and  respon- 
sibility by  the  President  to  the  heads  of  his  line  establishments  and  consolida- 
tion of  his  own  staff  contribute  greatly  to  success  in  administration.  How- 
ever, the  problems  and  concerns  of  the  departmental  system  ramify  so 
widely  and  intertwine  so  perplexingly  that  the  chief  executive  must  seek  to 
arrange  for  the  main  agencies  to  share  them  with  him  through  discussion 
and  decision  in  the  Cabinet.  As  a  collegial  body,  the  Cabinet  could  serve  as 
a  forum  for  debating  general  policy  recommendations,  and  aid  the  President 
in  formulating  such  proposals  in  true  teamwork.24  Cabinet  committees,  with 
the  participation  of  specialized  top  personnel,  could  set  themselves  the  task 
of  finding  a  common  approach  to  major  policy  issues  and  of  devising  a 
pattern  of  combined  operations  for  giving  effect  to  considered  solutions. 

22  See  above  Ch.  6,  "Planning  and  Administration/'  sec.  2,  'The  Machinery  for  Plan- 
ning." 

23  See  Morstein  Marx,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  14,  p.  898. 

24  Cf.  Macmahon,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  20,  p.  1 187. 


THE  CHIEF  EXECUTIVE  183 

Cabinet  meetings  might  well  include  the  key  men  of  the  President's  Execu- 
tive Office.  This  is  but  hopeful  speculation,  for  it  is  one  of  the  distinctive 
facts  about  our  federal  government  that  the  Cabinet  lives  in  a  kind  of 
dormant  state  as  a  device  for  making  policy.  However,  one  thing  is  certain. 
That  President  who  first  exploits  the  collective  potentialities  of  the  Cabinet 
as  a  regular  and  systematic  practice  will  make  a  signal  contribution  to  Amer- 
ican public  administration. 


CHAPTER 


The  Departmental  System 

1.   GENERAL  FEATURES 

Purpose  of  Departmentalization.  We  speak  of  departments  when  dealing 
with  parts  of  a  whole.  The  whole  may  be  a  unified  territory;  thus,  the  French 
departements  are  areas  into  which  the  country  is  divided  for  governmental 
purposes.  Or  the  whole  may  be  the  total  structure  of  political  organization; 
thus,  we  often  refer  to  the  three  main  powers  of  government,  set  apart  from 
one  another  under  our  Constitution,  as  the  legislative,  executive,  and  judicial 
departments.  Or  the  whole  may  be  the  machinery  of  administration  com- 
bined in  the  executive  branch;  thus, [we  have  long  recognized  the  need  for 
some  division  of  labor  in  the  administrative  system  by  grouping  more  or  less 
related  functions  under  formally  designated  departments^  It  is  with  depart- 
mentalization in  this  last  sense  that  we  shall  here  be  concerned. 
^Departmentalization,  being  in  essence  a  division  of  labor,  is  intended  to 
make  more  effective  rather  than  split  up  the  whole  within  which  it  is 
applied.1  When  organizations  grow  to  the  point  where  direction  and  control 
can  ndlonger  be  exercised  in  face-to-face  contact  between  the  leader  and  the 
rank  and  file,  intermediate  stages  of  leadership  must  be  supplied.  Such 
arrangements — though  marking  out  the  component  parts  within  the  whole — 
make  it  possible  to  keep  the  organization  in  formation  and  to  attain  efficient 
use  of  specialized  skills.  In  determining  the  scope  of  responsibility  on  each 
of  these  intermediate  stages  or  at  each  point  of  subdivision,  consideration 
must  be  given  to  two  elementary  propositions.  First,  it  is  essential  to  achieve 
the  greatest  measure  of  operational  unity  within  every  subdivision.  Second, 
it  is  necessary  to  establish  sound  working  relationships  among  all  sub- 
divisions. 

This  is  in  the  main  a  matter  of  economy  of  control.  Subleadership  is 
hopelessly  overburdened  when  compelled  to  putf  together  scattered  frag- 
ments of  different  activities.  It  is  also  easy  to/see  that  the  demands  on  sub- 
leadership  are  not  always  of  the  same  chararewv  In  large-scale  organizations, 
public  and  private,  the  higher  intermpdlatfe  itages  usually  require  special 

184 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  185 

capacity  for  ranging  over  broader  fields  and  for  marshaling  sizable  forces 
in  close  relationship  to  the  aims  of  the  organization  as  a  whole.  On  the 
other  hand,  subleadership  on  the  lower  intermediate  stages  down  to  the 
first-line  supervisor  increasingly  calls  for  technical  competence  with  respect 
to  specific  operations.  Even  the  first-line  supervisor,  however,  is  in  a  very 
practical  sense  an  agent  of  the  leader  of  the  entire  organization,  assisting 
him  in  attaining  the  ends  of  the  organization  at  large. 

The  way  in  which  the  whole  is  reenforced  through  identification  of  its 
parts  and  their  interrelations  provides  the  general  framework  of  adminis- 
trative organization.  Hierarchy,  lines  of  command,  levels  of  responsibility 
and  channels  of  administrative  communication  find  their  proper  place  within 
this  framework.  Departmentalization  represents  the  highest  intermediate 
stage  of  leadership  in  relation  to  the  chief  executive,  but  it  is  only  one  stage. 
Layer  after  layer,  division  of  labor  and  delegation  of  authority  progress 
downward  throughout  the  departmental  system.  Nevertheless,  the  first 
order  of  division,  on  the  departmental  plane,  is  of  decisive  importance  in 
giving  shape  to  the  bulk  of  the  lower  structure.  That  is  why  departmentali- 
zation, however  academic  much  of  the  discussion  about  it  may  be,  is  any- 
thing but  an  academic  matter. 

Structure  of  the  Departmental  System.  In  one  form  or  another,  and 
under  varying  labels,  departmentalization  occurs  in  all  organized  enterprise 
except  the  smallest  kind.  The  Phillips  Petroleum  Company,  for  instance, 
maintains  no  less  than  twenty-one  departments,  such  as  production,  refining, 
traffic,  and  sales  on  the  one  hand;  and  engineering,  research,  economics,  and 
public  relations  on  the  other.  The  Rochester  Gas  and  Electric  Corporation, 
another  illustration  chosen  at  random,  operates  through  about  eighteen  de- 
partments, some  of  which  are  in  the  nature  of  subdivisions  of  the  main  de- 
partments.1 To  mention  a  few  examples  in  the  field  of  government,  Ten- 
nessee, under  the  reorganization  acts  of  1923  and  1937,  placed  the  following 
departments  under  its  governor:  administration,  finance  and  taxation,  high- 
ways and  public  works,  conservation,  agriculture,  insurance  and  banking, 
labor,  education,  public  health,  and  institutions  and  public  welfare.2  The 
mayor  of  Boston  exercises  authority,  wholly  or  in  part,  over  a  much  larger 
number  of  departments,  including  fire,  health,  hospital,  public  welfare, 
institutions,  building,  city  planning,  street  laying-out,  public  buildings, 
school  buildings,  public  works,  transit,  park,  market,  weights  and  measures, 
and  library  and  art.8  The  village  manager  of  Winnetka,  Illinois,  has  only 
five  full-fledged  departments  to  be  concerned  with— police,  fire,  health,  pub- 

1Scc  Metropolitan  Life  Insurance  Company,  Policyholders  Service  Bureau,  Business  Organi- 
zation, supplemental  exhibits  A  and  C,  New  York,  1944.  This  is  one  of  a  series  of  helpful 
reports  on  business  management. 

2  See  Buck,  A.  E.,  The  Reorganization  of  State  Governments  in  the  United  States,  p.  229, 
New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1938. 

3  See  Boston  Municipal  Research  Bureau,  Report,  p.  4,  Boston,  Oct.  1937. 


186  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

lie  works,  and  water  and  electric.4  The  number  of  federal  executive  depart- 
ments has  been  kept  to  ten;  listed  on  the  basis  of  seniority,  they  are:  State, 
War,  Treasury  (the  original  trio  since  1789),  Navy  (1798),  Interior  (1849), 
Agriculture  (1862)  Justice  (1870),  Post  Office  (1872),  Commerce  (1903), 
and  Labor  (1913).5 

Considering  the  actual  scope  of  federal  activities,  it  may  at  first  glance 
look  like  a  marvelous  accomplishment  that  the  chief  executive  of  the  nation 
can  direct  these  activities  through  so  few  departments—less  than  a  third  of 
the  number  of  departments  that  cluster  about  the  Prime  Minister  in  Eng- 
land. But  the  first  glance  is  sadly  deceptive.  Historically,  we  started  out 
well  enough.  The  Founding  Fathers,  with  a  remarkably  acute  sense  of 
administration,  took  great  care  in  drawing  the  outlines  of  a  unified  executive 
branch.  However,  significant  departures  occurred  with  the  creation  of 
establishments  independent  of  the  President  save  for  his  appointing  power. 

The  principal  landmarks  in  this  new  development  were  the  Civil  Service 
Commission  (1883)  and  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  (1887), 
both  regulatory  bodies— the  former  vested  with  virtual  autonomy  in  recruit- 
ment for  federal  service  and  the  latter  well-nigh  uncontrolled  in  its  control 
over  the  national  transportation  system.  Through  the  years,  a  baker's  dozen 
of  similar  agencies  came  forth  on  the  precedent  of  these  two.  Add  to  this 
the  proliferation  of  governmental  corporations  and  separate  authorities, 
and  we  have  a  picture  of  the  diversity  and  diffusion  which  confronts  the 
chief  executive.  How  can  he  perform  his  constitutional  duties  as  head  of  the 
administrative  organization,  asked  the  President's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Management  in  1937,  when  he  must  deal  directly  with  one  hundred 
federal  agencies  of  one  kind  or  another?6  The  Reorganization  Act  of  1939 
authorized  some  integration  subject  to  statutory  limitations,  but  fell  short  of 
achieving  anything  like  a  final  solution.  How  far  the  Reorganization  Act 
of  1945  will  carry  us  in  this  respect,  remains  to  be  seen. 

Much  the  same  situation  prevails  in  state  and  local  governments.  Inde- 
pendent boards  and  commissions,  together  with  other  unattached  authorities 
of  comparable  status,  in  many  jurisdictions  compete  with  the  departmental 
machinery  controlled  by  the  governor  or  mayor.  The  chairman  of  a  munici- 
pal police  commission,  for  example,  may  exercise  greater  power  than  the 
nominal  principal  executive  of  the  city.  Moreover,  most  state  and  local 
governments  are  still  paying  heavy  tribute  to  the  long  ballot  of  old,  which 

4  See  Village  of  Winnctka,  III.,  Annual  Report  for  the  Fiscal  Year  ending  March  31,  1943 
p.  2. 

6  General  reference  may  be  made  in  this  context  to  the  United  States  Government  Manual, 
the  official  handbook  of  the  federal  government,  which  appears  in  up-to-date  editions  at  short 
intervals  and  which  may  be  obtained  from  the  Superintendent  of  Documents,  Government 
Printing  Office,  Washington,  D.  C. 

6  See  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Studies, 
Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937.  The  findings  and  recommendations  of  this 
committee  have  exerted  considerable  influence  on  subsequent  developments  and  still  represent 
an  important  source  of  pertinent  information. 


1KB  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  187 

was  based  on  the  philosophy  that  most,  if  not  ail,  offices  should  be  filled  by 
election.  Elective  officials  such  as  recorder,  treasurer,  and  comptroller,  hold- 
ing office  by  statutory  or  even  constitutional  provision,  may  be  thorns  in  the 
flesh  of  the  state  or  local  chief  executive.  Since  the  beginning  of  this  century, 
measurable  progress  has  been  made  toward  raising  governors  and  mayors 
to  true  responsibility  for  the  executive  branch,  and  the  continuous  spread  of 
the  council-manager  plan  of  municipal  government  has  worked  in  the  same 
direction.  However,  an  integrated  system  of  administration  is  even  now  the 
exception  rather  than  the  rule,  despite  many  notable  instances  of  state  and 
local  reorganization. 

Factors  in  Departmentalization.  Lest  our  failure  to  evolve  a  fully  satis- 
factory executive  structure  be  seized  upon  as  evidence  of  governmental 
floundering,  it  must  be  stressed  that  departmentalization  is  fraught  with 
complexities.7  These  are  in  part  technical,  in  part  political.  From  a  technical 
point  of  view,  it  is  difficult  to  determine  with  assurance  the  proper  basis  of 
departmental  organization.  Should  it  be  identity  of  major  purpose  to  be 
served  or  function  to  be  exercised,  such  as  national  defense,  social  welfare, 
and  urban  development?  Or  should  it  be  the  nature  of  the  process  or  the 
primary  skill  involved  in  it,  such  as  engineering,  licensing,  and  mimeo- 
graphing? Or  should  it  be  the  group  of  people  to  be  serviced,  such  as 
farmers,  veterans,  and  small  businessmen?  Or,  finally,  should  it  be  the 
territory  or  area  on  which  activities  should  be  focused,  such  as  New  England, 
the  Missouri  valley,  and  downstate  Illinois?  Speculating  on  the  feasibility 
of  each  such  basis,  we  are  bound  to  discover  soon  that  its  strict  and  exclu- 
sive application  leads  simultaneously  to  two  undesirable  consequences.  First, 
activities  that  belong  together  as  components  of  a  concrete  administrative 
end-product  are  torn  apart  at  various  points  and  in  varying  ways.  Second, 
if  reasonable  concessions  are  made  to  a  combination  of  activities  in  what 
might  be  termed  an  organic  manner  and  with  an  eye  to  the  end-product, 
activities  of  the  same  kind  appear  in  conjunction  with  others  at  many 
different  places  in  the  executive  branch. 

Classification  of  conceivable  bases  of  departmental  organization,  being 
"one  of  convenience  alone,"8  is  therefore  merely  a  useful  starting  point  for 
trying  to  piece  together  the  jigsaw  puzzle.  How  to  manipulate  the  classi- 
fication for  practical  ends  is  quite  another  matter.  Admitting  its  inability 
to  lay  down  a  few  simple  rules  of  the  game,  the  Brookings  Institution, 

7  See  Gulick,  Luther,  "Notes  on  the  Theory  of  Organization,"  in  Gulick,  Luther  and 
Urwick,  L.,  eds.,  Papers  on  the  Science  of  Administration,  p.  3  ff.,  New  York:    Institute  of 
Public  Administration,  1937;  Brookings  Institution,  Report  to  the  Byrd  Committee  on  Organi- 
zation of  the  Executive  Branch  of  the  National  Government,  Senate  Report  No.  1275,  75th 
Cong.,  1st  Scss.,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937;  Wallace,  Schuyier  C.,  Federal 
Departmentalization:  A  Critique  of  Theories  of  Organization,  New  York:   Columbia  University 
Press,  1941.  See  also  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  of  Organization." 

8  Benson,  George  C.  S.,   "Internal   Administrative  Organization,"  Public  Administration 
Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  473. 


188  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

advising  a  congressional  committee  several  years  ago,  suggested  a  cautious!) 
eclectic  approach:9 

No  single  factor  can  be  decisive  throughout  the  entire  organization. 
One  factor  may  help  us  to  decide  at  one  point;  elsewhere,  another  factor 
may  be  more  helpful.  At  every  point  one  determinant  must  be  balanced 
against  another.  For  some  functions  and  some  agencies  there  may  be 
no  one  best  course  of  action.  A  choice  may  be  presented  between  alterna- 
tives, one  as  desirable  as  the  other. 

This  does  not  sound  very  encouraging,  but  it  contains  more  than  a  grain 
of  truth.  Study  of  departmentalization,  like  all  administrative  analysis,  re- 
quires careful  penetration  into  the  total  situation  in  which  the  problem  to 
be  solved  is  lodged.  Technical  knowledge,  even  when  tested  in  the  hard 
school  of  practical  experience,  is  of  little  avail  unless  its  application  is  pre- 
ceded by  painstaking  and  skillful  diagnosis,  not  only  of  the  ill  to  be  reme- 
died, but  also  of  all  the  factors  that  bear  upon  both  the  ill  and  the  possible 
remedies. 

Aside  from  its  technical  compexities,  departmentalization  is  also  beset 
with  political  issues.  No  sooner  has  a  department  been  established  than  it 
will  become  enamoured  with  itself.  However  extraordinary  the  conglomera- 
tion of  activities  packed  into  it  by  way  of  compromise,  it  will  presently 
associate  itself  with  each  of  them  in  unfaltering  fondness.  Talk  about 
shifting  any  of  these  activities  to  some  other  department — as  subsequent 
events  may  indicate  to  be  the  better  logic — and  argument  breaks  loose.  Then 
also,  departmental  officialdom  naturally  inclines  toward  taking  an  expansive 
view  of  the  department's  mandate.  As  the  department  grows  bigger  and 
better  (which  to  its  leadership  may  be  one  and  the  same  thing),  it  inevitably 
begins  to  impinge  upon  related  activities  carried  on  by  other  departments. 
Again,  there  will  be  a  lot  of  fussing  and  fuming  when  lines  of  demarcation 
must  be  redrawn.  Each  time  the  department  will  muster  persuasive  reasons 
for  keeping  what  it  has  "always"  had,  or  what  "belongs  to  it"— at  least  by 
implication;  and  its  arguments  are  likely  to  evoke  a  vigorous  echo  among 
the  loyal  clientele  of  special  interests  and  pressure  groups  that  have  lined 
up  within  its  ramparts.  Usually  the  noise  alone  is  enough  to  intimidate 
reform. 

Moreover,  executive  reorganization  is  a  somewhat  obscure  art  and 
more  than  a  little  suspect  among  the  entrenched  interests  inside  and  outside 
the  departmental  system.  Suspicion  begets  hostility  and  resistance.  Institu- 
tional resistance  may  be  deliberate,  but  it  may  arise  also  from  the  inertia 
of  settled  form.  The  cumulative  effect  has  been  one  of  inordinate  immobility. 
Looking  at  the  departmental  structure,  we  may  be  reminded  of  "monsters 
with  great  defensive  power  developed  at  the  expense  of  movement  and 
intellect,"  as  Pendleton  Herring  has  so  aptly  put  it.10 

9  Op.  fit.  in  note  7,  p.  43. 

10  "Executive-Legislative  Responsibilities,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol. 
38,  p.  1161. 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  189 

In  the  face  of  such  "monsters,"  the  feeble  voice  of  organizational  com- 
monsense  is  none  too  effective.  Exceptional  circumstances  must  come  to  the 
fore  in  order  to  provide  the  psychological  moment  for  thoroughgoing 
realignment.  Circumstances  of  this  kind  are  relatively  rare.  But  they  are 
frequent  enough  to  warrant  continuous  structural  planning  by  a  central 
staff  agency  such  as  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  in  the  Executive  Office  of  the 
President.  Continuous  planning  is  necessary  because  changing  national 
needs  and  emerging  reorientation  of  policy  usually  affect  the  departmental 
system  to  a  greater  or  lesser  extent.  Here,  as  elsewhere,  preparedness  pays. 
When  the  day  for  constructive  action  arrives,  the  whole  opportunity  may 
hinge  on  the  immediate  availability  of  fully  considered  proposals  for 
reorganization. 

Undirected  Growth.  The  technical  and  political  difficulties  which  sur- 
round departmentalization  account  in  large  measure  for  the  fact  that  the 
structure  of  the  executive  branch  has  been  traditionally  the  product  of 
"undirected  growth,"  in  Leonard  D.  White's  descriptive  phrase.  To  put 
it  differently,  rarely  if  ever  have  we  tried  to  project  existing  and  emerging 
governmental  activities  in  terms  of  a  comprehensive  organizational  plan. 
On  the  other  han|J,  judging  by  our  experience  with  state  and  local  reorgani- 
zation, we  must  admit  that  a  neatly  conceived  general  formula  yields  only 
limited  results  unless  its  application  is  accompanied  by  a  change  of  insti- 
tutional atmosphere.  This  would  have  to  include  a  corresponding  strength- 
ening of  enlightened  management,  a  better  personnel  system,  and  greater 
legislative  self-restraint  in  tampering  with  the  departmental  scheme  on 
partisan  impulse.  Reorganization  has  been  abused  as  a  political  football 
more  often  than  we  might  think.  Nor  has  the  game  lost  its  attraction  to 
those  who  know  how  to  play.  A  notable  recent  instance  occurred  in  1945  when 
the  Senate  was  asked  to  confirm  former  Vice  President  Henry  A.  Wallace 
as  Secretary  of  Commerce.  He  had  proved  himself  earlier  an  able  Secretary 
of  Agriculture.  Yet  confirmation  was  attainable  only  after  responsibility 
for  extensive  governmental  credit  activities  had  been  severed  from  the 
Department  of  Commerce  and  made  the  concern  of  a  separate  agency. 

The  alliance  between  institutional  inertia,  vested  interests,  and  political 
partisanship  throws  an  enormous  weight  of  support  behind  the  departmental 
status  quo.  Stability  of  organization  is  in  itself  an  asset,  because  for  greatest 
efficiency  everyone  must  know  his  way  within  the  organization  as  a  matter 
of  habit.  Indeed,  habit  born  of  repetition  or  indoctrination  minimizes  the 
effects  even  of  grossly  deformed  organization.  However,  stability  becomes 
a  vice  when  it  is  maintained  at  the  price  of  structural  simplicity  and  balance. 
It  shows  itself  as  a  particularly  serious  vice  when  we  consider  the  usual  time 
lag  between  established  governmental  form  ajid  the  evermoving  substance 
of  social  and  economic  life.  On  practical  grounds,  therefore,  we  should 
strive  for  a  permanent  legislative-executive  arrangement  under  which  appro- 
priate organizational  adjustments  and  modifications  in  the  executive  branch 


190  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

can  be  made  in  harmony  with  changing  needs.  The  legislature  would  pro- 
vide the  frame  of  reference,  and  the  chief  executive  would  take  action 
within  the  scope  of  his  authorization.  This  is  what  Herbert  Hoover,  then 
Secretary  of  Commerce,  proposed  in  1924  before  the  Joint  Congressional 
Committee  on  the  Reorganization  of  the  Administrative  Branch.  The 
Reorganization  Act  of  1939 — though  conceding  only  temporary  authority — 
followed  the  line  of  Hoover's  reasoning.  It  called  for  reorganization  plans 
formulated  by  the  President  to  be  submitted  to  Congress,  which  reserved 
to  itself  the  right  of  disapproval.11  Under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1945, 
the  same  general  prescription  has  been  used  for  the  postwar  period,  because 
the  two  War  Powers  Acts  of  World  War  II— temporary  grants  of  merely 
temporary  effect  modeled  on  the  Overman  Act  of  World  War  I — were 
designed  specifically  for  only  war-emergency  duration.12 

Because  departmentalization  aims  to  increase  the  effectiveness  of  the 
whole  rather  than  partition  it,  the  number  of  main  divisions  is  important 
from  the  angle  of  direction  by  the  chief  executive.  His  physical  span  of 
control  is  naturally  limited.  Reasonably  exact  measurement  would  differ 
with  different  personalities.  But  for  each  personality  the  limit  is  easily 
reached,  especially  if  we  keep  in  mind  that  a  smaller  numfcer  of  departments 
in  turn  may  involve  too  wide  a  span  of  control  for  the  department  heads, 
thus  shifting  the  problem  to  the  next  lower  level.  Inflexible  restriction  of 
the  number  of  departments  is  therefore  no  adequate  answer,  whether  such 
restriction  be  imposed  constitutionally,  as  it  has  been  in  several  states,  or  by 
statute,  as  it  was  in  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  here  primarily  as  a  check 
on  the  President's  range  of  structural  choice. 

Quasi-Departments.  Although  no  new  "departments"  were  to  be  created 
under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,  three  quasi-departments  came  into 
being:  the  Federal  Security  Agency,  the  Federal  Works  Agency,  and  the 
Federal  Loan  Agency.  Each  absorbed  into  itself  a  multitude  of  adminis- 
trative establishments,  many  of  which  had  formerly  not  known  a  common 
denominator.  We  may  doubt  very  much  whether  the  grouping  of  quite 
diversified  lending  activities  under  a  quasi-department— and  hence  without 
close  relationship  to  broader  substantive  programs — was  a  sound  move.  The 
fact  remains,  however,  that  the  three  new  agencies  brought  measurable 
relief  to  the  overburdened  chief  executive.  As  for  internal  integration  within 
each  new  agency,  it  is  hardly  surprising  that  initially  there  was  more 
similarity  to  a  holding  company  than  to  a  department. 

11  For  greater  detail   see  Millett,  John  D.  and  Rogers,  Lindsay,  "The  Legislative  Veto 
and  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  176  ff.  A 
brief  history  of  federal  reorganization  efforts  may  be  found  in  Meriam,  Lewis  and  Schmccke- 
bier,  Laurence  F.,  Reorganization  of  the  National  Government,  p.  181  ff.,  Washington:  Brook- 
ings  Institution,  1939. 

12  For  an  illuminating  and  authoritative  preview,  see  Brownlow,  Louis,  "Reconversion  of 
the  Federal  Administrative  Machinery  from  War  to  Peace,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1944, 
Vol.  4,  p.  309  ff.  The  author  served  as  the  chairman  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Management;  see  above  note  6. 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  191 

The  common  denominator  does  not  spring  from  mere  pronouncement. 
It  must  be  fostered  systematically  over  a  longer  period  before  it  translates 
itself  into  a  point  of  view  commonly  shared  throughout  the  agency.  In 
general,  formation  of  quasi-departments  is  an  ingenious  device  for  provid- 
ing the  executive  branch  with  an  experimental  fringe.  Activity  groupings 
may  thus  be  tried  out  in  practice,  and  legislative  assent  to  full  departmental 
status  may  be  bought  by  demonstration  of  performance.  This  applies  also 
to  such  essentially  permanent  establishments  as  the  National  Housing 
Agency,  a  merger  of  several  no  longer  novel  federal  programs  which  might 
have  come  about  under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  but  actually  took 
place  under  the  First  War  Powers  Act  of  1941  and  thus  required  further 
legislation  for  its  continued  effectiveness. 

2.  INTERDEPARTMENTAL  COORDINATION 

Before  the  consolidations  made  possible  by  the  Reorganization  Act  of 
1939  had  reached  the  point  of  full  returns,  the  gradual  transformation  from 
peace  to  war  expressed  itself  in  the  creation  of  many  new  agencies.  Coordi- 
nation became  a  burning  issue.  The  way  this  issue  was  met  is  likely  to  have 
wider  significance.  In  the  first  place  a  considerable  degree  of  coordination 
was  achieved  through  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  doubtless  the 
outstanding  product  brought  forth  under  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939.13 
One  of  its  divisions,  the  Office  for  Emergency  Management,  furnished  the 
nominal  link  between  the  chief  executive  and  most — though  not  all — of  the 
new  machinery.  In  the  initial  period,  it  also  exerted  some  real  coordinative 
and  prompting  influence.  More  important  in  the  whole  development  was 
the  role  of  another  division  of  the  Executive  Office,  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget. 
The  latter,  established  in  1921  as  the  President's  first  staff  agency,  came 
to  reflect  him  in  administration,  in  Arthur  Macmahon's  appraisal.14  Sec- 
ondly, as  the  pressures  and  frictions  within  the  quickly  expanding  executive 
branch  increased  and  as  action  programs  acquired  red-hot  priority,  officials 
in  charge  of  such  programs  were  authorized  to  assume  directive  powers  in 
broad  fields,  binding  upon  all  operating  agencies  active  in  these  fields.  This 
was  true  of  the  heads  of  the  War  Production  Board  and  the  War  Manpower 
Commission.  Later,  successively  wider  coordinative  mandates  were  en- 
trusted to  the  director  of  the  Office  of  Economic  Stabilization  (1942)  and  the 
director  of  the  Office  of  War  Mobilization  (1943),  afterwards  the  statutory 
Office  of  War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion. 


13  A  highly  informative  symposium  on  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President  in  its  original 
form  by  Louis  Brownlow  and  Others  was  published  in  Public  Administration  Review,  1941, 
Vol.  1,  p.   101  ff.    The  reader  should  bear  in  mind  that   subsequently  two   divisions  of  the 
Executive  Office  disappeared.    The  Office  of  Government  Reports  was  disbanded  as  such,  and 
the  National  Resources  Planning  Board  died  of  legislative  antagonism. 

14  "The  Future  Organizational  Pattern  of  the  Executive  Branch,"  American  Political  Scienct 
Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1182.    A  helpful  review  of  war  developments  is  offered  by  Gulick> 
Luther,  "War  Organization  of  the  Federal  Government,"  ibid.,  p.  1166  ff. 


192  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

Staff  Establishments.  To  place  reliance  for  interdepartmental  coordina- 
tion on  officers  or  offices  that  serve  the  chief  executive  in  a  staff  capacity 
and  exercise  authority  essentially  in  his  name  and  by  his  direction  is  not  a 
novel  tendency.  Provision  for  such  assistance  has  been  a  typical  concern 
of  state  and  local  reorganization  for  several  decades.  It  was  expressed  most 
frequendy  in  the  centralization  of  expenditure  control  under  a  budget 
agency  attached  to  the  office  of  the  governor,  mayor,  or  city  manager.  A 
milestone  was  set  in  1917  when  Illinois  introduced  such  a  budget  system 
into  its  state  administration.  Municipalities  followed  the  same  path.  The 
Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921  carried  the  much-publicized  prescrip- 
tion into  the  federal  government.  By  equipping  the  President  with  a  special 
agency,  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  to  aid  him  in  shaping  up,  year  after  year, 
the  annual  work  plan  of  the  government  for  consideration  and  adoption  by 
Congress,  this  act  reversed  the  former  trend  toward  departmental  self-deter- 
mination and  independence.  In  constructing  the  general  program  of  agency 
estimates  of  appropriations,  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  could  correlate  the 
activities  undertaken  throughout  the  executive  branch,  and  thus  give  a 
substantial  impetus  to  interdepartmental  coordination  as  well  as  to  the 
improvement  of  administrative  management. 

With  the  establishment  in  1939  of  the  President's  Executive  Office,  the 
Bureau  of  the  Budget,  as  an  integral  part  of  the  new  nucleus,  underwent  a 
conspicuous  expansion  in  order  to  become  one  of  the  "principal  management 
arms  of  the  Government."15  Through  its  growing  professional  staff,  it  was 
able  to  furnish  practical  help  at  numerous  points  in  the  conversion  of  the 
administrative  system  from  peacetime  needs  to  wartime  demands,  and  in 
spreading  knowledge  of  tested  methods  and  practices.  The  broad  range  of 
this  kind  of  combined  consulting  and  installation  service  supplied  the  bureau 
with  unusual  opportunities  for  spotting  undetected  weaknesses  of  organi- 
zation and  management  in  the  unfolding  war  administration.  Depending 
on  the  character  of  the  problems  and  obstacles  which  it  encountered  in  its 
remedial  efforts,  the  bureau  on  many  occasions  placed  issues  before  the 
President  which  would  ordinarily  not  have  come  to  his  early  attention.  In 
numerous  instances,  these  issues  involved  clarification  of  jurisdictional  boun- 
daries and  adjustment  of  programs  for  better  coordination  of  different 
agencies  that  somehow  had  got  in  one  another's  way. 

Simultaneously,  the  bureau  kept  its  eyes  on  the  attainment  of  dominant 
wartime  objectives  through  concerted  action  by  several  federal  agencies, 
from  the  point  of  view  of  both  adequate  administrative  planning  and  syn- 
chronized execution.  This  entailed  working  contacts  with  planning  staffs 
and  operating  officials  in  various  parts  of  the  executive  branch,  and  also  the 
combined  boards  and  similar  devices  by  which  the  United  States  secured 
cooperation  with  Great  Britain,  Canada,  and  other  members  of  the  United 

15  This  is  the  language  of  Executive  Order  No.  8248  of  September  8,  1939,  which  may 
be  called  the  original  charter  of  the  President's  Executive  Office.  See  also  above  note  13. 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  193 

Nations.16  Aside  from  such  working  contacts,  the  bureau  exercised  its 
budgetary  authority  for  coordinative  purposes.  The  same  end  was  furthered 
in  connection  with  the  bureau's  review  for  conformity  with  the  President's 
program  of  agency  proposals  for  legislation  or  executive  orders,  and  agency 
reports  to  congressional  committees  on  pending  bills.  Another  avenue  of 
coordination  presented  itself  in  the  bureau's  responsibility,  under  the  Reports 
Act  of  1942,  for  approving  agency  plans  for  statistical  inquiries  addressed  to 
the  public.  Additional  pertinent  authorities  were  included  in  the  war  over- 
time pay  legislation  and  its  successor,  the  Federal  Employees  Pay  Act  of 
1945,  under  which  the  budget  director  determines  periodically  the  personnel 
requirements  of  federal  agencies. 

Coordinating  Agencies.  Compared  with  the  implicit  and  broadly  inclu- 
sive coordinating  mandate  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  the  wartime  inno- 
vations for  pulling  together  governmental  activities  in  order  to  "hold  the 
line"  against  inflation  and  to  organize  all  of  the  productive  resources  of  the 
country  for  greatest  striking  power  appear  as  explicit  and  specific  grants  of 
authority.  The  evolving  pattern  became  clear  with  the  formation  of  the 
Office  of  Economic  Stabilization;  it  later  found  its  sharpest  expression  in 
the  tasks  assigned  to  the  new  Office  of  War  Mobilization.  The  director  of 
the  Office  of  War  Mobilization  was  charged  with  the  duty  "to  unify  the 
activities  of  the  federal  agencies  .  .  .  engaged  in  or  concerned  with  produc- 
tion, procurement,  distribution,  or  transportation  of  military  or  civilian 
supplies,  materials,  or  products."  He  was  also  to  "resolve  or  determine 
controversies  between  such  agencies,"  except  those  falling  into  the  jurisdic- 
tion of  the  Office  of  Economic  Stabilization.  In  exercising  these  functions, 
he  was  entitled  to  "issue  such  directives  on  policy  or  operations  to  the  federal 
agencies  ...  as  may  be  necessary  to  carry  out  the  programs  developed,  the 
policies  established,  and  the  decisions  made"  under  his  authority,  and  to 
call  for  progress  reports  from  any  of  the  agencies  subject  to  his  directives. 
In  basic  conception,  the  pattern  fashioned  by  executive  orders  issued  in 
1942  and  1943  under  the  President's  wartime  powers  was  reaffirmed  in  the 
War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion  Act  of  1944.  In  this  law  the  renamed 
Office  of  War  Mobilization  and  Reconversion  emerged  as  a  statutory  estab' 
lishment,"  incorporating  within  itself  three  equally  temporary  demobilization 
agencies  having  kindred  supervisory  concerns:  the  Office  of  Contract  Settle- 
ment, the  Surplus  War  Property  Administration,  and  the  Retraining  and 
Reemployment  Administration.17 

Thus  there  had  arisen,  side  by  side  with  more  traditional  coordinating 

m  Operation  of  the  combined  machinery  has  been  looked  upon  by  many  as  a  rehearsal 
for  peacetime  international  organization;  see,  for  instance,  Salter,  Arthur,  "From  Combined  War 
Agencies  to  International  Administration,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  1  ff. 
The  author  is  an  old  hand  at  combined  business;  his  study  of  Allied  shipping  control  during 
World  War  I,  published  in  1921,  is  still  of  great  value. 

17  The  progress  of  demobilization  planning  has  been  traced  by  Key,  V.  O.,  "The  Recon- 
version Phase  of  Demobilization,*'  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1137  ff. 


194  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

machinery  as  exemplified  by  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  an  impressive 
hierarchy  of  coordinators,  with  the  War  Mobilization,  and  Reconversion 
director  closest  to  the  apex.  He  was  not  exactly  at  the  apex  because  he  had 
to  share  the  loftly  heights  with  others,  primarily  representatives  of  the 
military  services,  including  the  Joint  Chiefs  of  Staff,  and  spokesmen  of 
foreign  policy,  especially  the  Secretary  of  State.  Although  in  large  part  a 
makeshift  arrangement,  the  new  hierarchy  of  wartime  coordinators  was 
instrumental  in  settling  countless  questions  which  normally  would  have 
plagued  the  chief  executive  without  really  requiring  his  consideration. 
Delegation  of  some  of  his  authority  proved  to  be  the  answer  to  the  riddle 
of  unified  administrative  operation. 

This  sounds  quite  simple.  But  the  specific  character  of  such  delegation 
had  to  be  worked  out  experimentally.  Men  had  to  be  found  to  try  their 
hand  at  tentative  assignments,  never  knowing  at  the  start  whether  they 
would  fit  into  the  personal  working  habits  of  an  executive  head  who  at  the 
very  beginning  of  the  defense  organization  for  war  needs  had  proclaimed 
himself  emphatically  "the  boss."  And  prestige  had  to  be  built  up  for  these 
men  so  that  operating  officials  would  actually  take  orders  without  thoughts 
of  appeal  or  evasion.  All  of  this  called  for  more  than  mouth-filling  clauses 
written  into  executive  orders. 

Although  interdepartmental  coordination  had  gained  the  upper  hand 
over  departmental  friction  during  the  closing  years  of  World  War  II,  it 
did  not  exactly  leave  us  an  accepted  prototype  for  peacetime  use.  In  the 
first  place,  the  somewhat  haphazard  stratification  of  coordinative  layers 
wedged  between  the  chief  executive  and  the  departmental  system  in  its 
wartime  enlargement  in  itself  resulted  in  a  good  deal  of  uncertainty.  A 
simpler  postwar  setup  appears  highly  desirable,  with  fewer  layers  and 
still  greater  precision  in  responsibilities.  Second,  the  hierarchy  of  coordi- 
nators with  their  own  special  staffs  seemed  to  pose  a  contradiction  to  the 
fundamental  idea  embodied  in  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President. 

Each  coordinator  reflected  an  element  of  power  derived  directly  from 
the  basic  function  of  the  chief  executive  as  the  constitutional  overseer  of  the 
departmental  scheme.  To  differentiate  between  the  "arms  of  management" 
supplied  in  the  Executive  Office  and  special  arms  of  coordination  might  be 
a  strenuous  exercise  in  semantics.  Some  of  the  special  arms  of  coordination, 
it  is  true,  were  nominally  part  of  the  Executive  Office,  through  the  fiction 
of  an  integrated  Office  for  Emergency  Management;  this  applied,  for  in- 
stance, to  the  chairmen  of  the  War  Production  Board  and  the  War  Man- 
power Commission.  However,  in  both  fact  and  physical  location,  these  first- 
line  coordinators  were  none  too  close  to  the  White  House.  Closest  to  it,  and 
actually  in  it  most  of  the  time,  was  the  head  of  the  Office  of  War  Mobiliza- 
tion and  Reconversion;  but  he,  interestingly,  was  never  organizationally 
included  in  the  Executive  Office.  The  institutional  gap  between  him  and  the 
Bureau  of  the  Budget  would  probably  have  caused  difficulties  save  for 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  195 

generally  satisfactory  working  relationships,  insisted  upon  by  President 
Roosevelt  himself. 

A  third  factor  is  perhaps  still  more  important.  Under  the  War  Mobiliza- 
tion and  Reconversion  Act  of  1944,  the  top  coordinator  of  the  home  front 
assumed  a  statutory  office  under  specifications  that  tended  to  pull  him 
toward  congressional  rather  than  presidential  superintendence.  To  that  ex- 
tent the  law  impinged  visibly  on  "the  orthodox  administrative  doctrine  that 
organs  of  direction  should  occupy  a  staff  relation  to  the  chief  executive."18 
Here,  again,  we  perceive  possibilities  of  dissonances. 

A  statutory  "Assistant  President,"  gravitating  toward  Congress  because 
of  special  reporting  obligations,  may  severely  limit  the  President's  directive 
power.  His  presence  also  may  cause  strain  in  the  President's  use  of  the  "arms 
of  management"  provided  in  the  Executive  Office.  Or,  if  there  is  instead  of 
an  "Assistant  President"  the  head  of  a  superdepartment  in  charge  of  pro- 
gram formulation  and  program  coordination  over  wider  areas  of  the 
departmental  system,  might  not  such  statutory  relationship  with  the  legis- 
lature narrow  unduly  the  President's  control  over  the  line-up  of  operating 
agencies?  Coordination  above  the  departmental  level  is  part  and  parcel 
of  the  President's  executive  function.  Such  coordination  can  only  be 
achieved  by  his  direction,  based  on  the  same  principle  on  which  rests  the 
exercise  of  authority  by  his  "arms  of  management."  It  appears  to  follow 
that  for  best  results  coordinative  assistance  should  be  rendered  to  the  Presi- 
dent within  the  framework  of  his  appropriately  regrouped  Executive  Office. 
Managerial  coordination  by  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  and  directive  co- 
ordination by  a  special  officer  cannot  be  separated  organizationally. 

Role  of  the  Cabinet.  Nothing  has  been  said  thus  far  about  the  Cabinet 
as  a  coordinating  mechanism,  and  for  good  reasons.  It  is  customary  to  point 
out  that  in  contrast  with  Great  Britain  the  American  assembly  of  depart- 
ment heads  as  a  consultative  body  is  devoid  of  constitutional  standing,  in 
the  states  as  well  as  in  the  federal  government.  Nor  is  the  matter  different 
in  our  municipalities.  Where  governor's  or  mayor's  councils  exist,  they  are 
generally  special  advisory  establishments  for  particular  purposes.  Whereas 
the  British  War  Cabinet,  in  both  World  War  I  and  World  War  II,  served 
as  one  of  the  foremost  devices  for  tightening  up  the  departmental  system, 
in  the  United  States  the  accelerated  pace  of  critical  times  seems  to  bring 
about  almost  the  opposite  result.  Woodrow  Wilson  did  find  it  convenient 
to  meet  regularly  with  the  key  figures  of  his  war  administration,  but  work- 
ing relations  among  various  agencies  rarely  dominated  the  agenda.  Franklin 
D.  Roosevelt  took  no  inspiration  from  Wilson's  example  and  managed  to 
keep  the  circle  of  his  close  advisers  for  the  most  part  in  fairly  constant 
motion.  The  parallel  with  the  "brain  trust"  of  the  thirties  suggests  itself, 
including  the  rate  of  turnover.  In  this  picture  the  Cabinet's  contribution  was 

18  Key,  he.  cit.  in  note  17,  p.  1152. 


196  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

reduced  to  the  fact  that  it  continued  to  meet  without  ever  becoming  a 
central  cog. 

One  explanation  of  the  difference  between  British  and  American  prac- 
tice in  this  respect  is  usually  left  unmentioned.  In  England,  the  Cabinet 
puts  heavy  responsibility  for  the  effective  conduct  of  its  business  on  a  com- 
petently staffed  secretariat.  This  secretariat,  in  its  developed  form  the 
institutional  offspring  of  World  War  I,  sees  to  it  that  all  matters  on  the 
docket,  except  last-minute  propositions  of  great  urgency,  are  checked  and 
cleared  to  the  point  where  the  issue  can  be  disposed  of  by  a  decision  offer- 
ing promise  of  finality.  With  us,  notwithstanding  the  existence  of  the 
Executive  Office,  comparable  facilities  for  continuous  cross-referencing 
are  still  lacking.  Small  wonder  that  Cabinet  meetings  tend  to  revolve 
around  summaries  of  developments  presented  by  the  President  himself, 
and  items  of  departmental  concern  brought  up  by  individual  secretaries  but 
rarely  of  true  interest  to  the  Cabinet  as  a  whole.  Although  sound  sugges- 
tions have  occasionally  been  advanced  for  a  vitalization  of  the  Cabinet,10 
decisive  change  is  hardly  in  the  offing  as  long  as  we  do  not  build  up  an 
adequate  secretariat. 

Use  of  Interdepartmental  Committees.  Before  we  leave  the  subject  of 
interdepartmental  coordination,  a  word  on  the  use  of  special  committees 
is  in  order.  Such  committees  combining  representatives  of  several  agencies 
for  joint  deliberation  of  matters  of  common  interest  or  wider  ramification 
are  nothing  new.  We  find  illustrations  on  all  three  levels  of  government — 
federal,  state,  and  local.  Shortly  after  its  inception,  the  Bureau  of  the 
Budget  began  to  surround  itself  with  a  growing  array  of  interdepartmental 
committees  which,  under  varying  names,  attended  to  the  inauguration  of 
better  management.  Collectively,  they  came  to  be  known  as  the  Coordinat- 
ing Service,  steered  by  a  chief  coordinator  who  in  turn  reported  to  the 
director  of  the  bureau.  The  Coordinating  Service  was  supported  by  a 
regional  organization  of  its  own,  which  linked  itself  to  the  more  than  three 
hundred  federal  business  associations  composed  of  ranking  federal  field 
officials  in  as  many  cities  throughout  the  land.  In  the  early  twenties,  these 
interdepartmental  arrangements  gave  considerable  drive  to  the  improvement 
of  governmental  business  practices.  But  in  the  course  of  time  the  effort 
spent  itself,  and  the  Coordinating  Service  died  of  stagnation.  It  was  form- 
ally abolished  in  1933.  Atrophy  had  also  weakened  the  remaining  federal 
business  associations. 

Many  other  interdepartmental  committees,  however,  continued  to  pursue 
their  missions  in  the  executive  branch.  One  notable  example  was  the  Cen- 
tral Statistical  Board,  later  transferred  to  the  President's  Executive  Office 
and  perpetuated  as  the  Division  of  Statistical  Standards  in  the  Bureau  of 
the  Budget.  Throughout  the  lifetime  of  this  board,  coordinating  functions 

19  See,  for  instance,  Macmahon,  loc.  cit.  in  note  14,  p.  1187.  See  also  above  Ch.  8,  "The 
Chief  Executive,"  sec.  5,  "Arms  of  Management" 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  197 

were  in  the  foreground  of  its  program.  The  same  can  be  said  of  the  Com- 
mittee on  Trade  Agreements  brought  together  under  auspices  of  the  State 
Department.  A  more  recent  instance  was  the  creation  in  the  State  Depart- 
ment of  an  Executive  Committee  for  Economic  Foreign  Policy,  which  may 
prove  itself  a  very  important  interdepartmental  arrangement.20 

With  all  that,  we  are  far  from  possessing  on  any  of  the  three  levels  of 
government  a  comprehensively  interlocking  committee  system.  Nor  should 
we  expect  too  much  from  it  if  we  had  one.  For,  in  the  nature  of  things, 
interdepartmental  committees  seldom  feel  the  directive  push  from  above. 
They  function  on  condition  of  agreement,  and  may  deteriorate  into  trading 
posts  where  stubborn  parties  bicker  for  their  own  advantages.  Apparently, 
such  committees  work  best  on  the  basis  of  specific  terms  of  reference,  with 
a  membership  picked  for  sufficient  authority  or  technical  knowledge  to 
facilitate  mutual  commitment,  and  under  alert  and  vigorous  leadership. 
When  these  conditions  prevail,  interdepartmental  committees  may  repay 
many  times  the  administrative  effort  invested  in  them. 

Avenues  of  Progress.  In  the  perspective  of  interdepartmental  coordi- 
nation, the  departmental  system  shows  itself  as  a  massive  conglomeration 
which  does  not  readily  respond  to  the  reins  held  by  the  chief  executive.  Ad- 
ministrative agencies  are  apt  to  become  personifications  of  a  purpose  en- 
dowed by  legislative  action  and  guarded  by  interest  assortments  that  regard 
themselves  as  the  lawful  beneficiaries  of  the  endowment.  The  result  is 
reluctance  toward  whole-hearted  acceptance  of  executive  control.  Centrifugal 
tendencies  are  therefore  innate  in  the  departmental  structure.  A  concert 
of  forces  is  attainable  only  through  continuous  assertion  of  direction  from 
the  top. 

Realistically  speaking,  this  means  that  coordinative  effort  plays  the 
role  of  a  counterpressure.  It  is  never  supreme,  but  it  may  go  far  toward 
accomplishing  a  relatively  high  degree  of  homogeneity  of  general  orienta- 
tion. Organization  charts  of  the  executive  branch  tend  to  display  reas- 
suringly straight  lines  of  command  and  responsibility.  In  certain  ways, 
however,  a  more  appropriate  comparison  might  be  that  with  a  feudal 
pattern  of  higher  and  lower  fiefs  in  which  the  vassals  are  sometimes  torn 
between  conflicting  loyalties,  and  where  designation  of  rank  is  often  a  very 
misleading  index  of  actual  power  and  influence. 

Looking  ahead  with  our  eyes  on  the  national  goal  of  high-level  employ- 
ment, we  can  discern  some  of  the  problems  that  closely  bear  upon  the 


20  For  an  informative  appraisal  of  federal  experience  in  this  field,  see  Reynolds,  Mary  T., 
Interdepartmental  Committees  in  the  National  Administration,  New  York:  Columbia  University 
Press,  1939.  The  role  of  interdepartmental  machinery  within  the  State  Department  is  indicated 
in  Laves,  Walter  H.  C.  and  Wilcox,  Francis  O.,  "Organizing  the  Government  for  Participation 
in  World  Affairs,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  913  ff.  Sec  also  two 
related  papers  by  the  same  authors  under  the  tides  "The  Reorganization  of  the  Department  of 
State,"  ibid.,  p.  289  ff.,  and  "The  State  Department  Continues  Its  Reorganization,"  ibid.,  1945, 
Vol.  39,  p.  309  ff. 


198  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

general  organization  of  the  executive  branch.  When  integrated  economic 
policy  and  coordinated  application  of  regulatory  and  stimulative  mechan- 
isms are  at  a  premium,  we  must  aim  at  three  cardinal  things.  First,  while 
adding  to  the  strength  of  top  coordination  in  planning  as  well  as  in  execu- 
tion, we  must  decrease  the  exorbitant  strain  on  the  chief  executive  by 
providing  supplementary  opportunities  for  synthesis  through  broader  re- 
grouping of  departmental  spheres  or  stronger  machinery  for  interdepart- 
mental cooperation.  This  need  is  particularly  acute  in  such  fields  as 
provision  for  unified  national  defense,  conduct  of  postwar  foreign  affairs, 
maintenance  of  industrial  peace,  and  integration  of  authority  over  trans- 
portation, including  aviation.  Second,  as  soon  as  we  think  of  the  impli- 
cations of  departmental  regrouping  to  further  these  ends,  the  question  of 
the  independent  regulatory  boards  and  commissions  comes  to  mind. 
Independence  from  the  chief  executive  in  combination  with  segmentation 
of  regulatory  assignments  between  a  variety  of  such  agencies  spells  serious 
inadequacy.  The  postwar  need  for  dealing  with  the  economy  in  terms  of 
widely  inclusive  consistency  does  not  accord  with  multiplicity  of  inde- 
pendent regulatory  bodies.  Much  of  this  is  also  pertinent  to  the  future 
role  of  governmental  corporations.  And  third,  sound  staff  work  within 
a  more  comprehensive  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  with  full  partici- 
pation of  agency  staffs,  will  be  an  indispensable  requirement.  Invigoration  of 
the  staff  function  cannot  be  long  delayed  lest  government  itself  be  chal- 
lenged in  its  role  of  protecting  the  enterprise  economy  against  fateful  shocks. 

3,  THE  SECRETARY'S  BUSINESS 

In  federal  administration,  the  title  of  secretary  is  confined  to  the  heads 
of  eight  of  the  ten  executive  departments;  the  remaining  two  department 
heads  are  designated  as  Attorney  General  and  as  Postmaster  General. 
However,  in  this  discussion  of  the  secretary's  business  we  shall  apply  the 
term  generically.  That  is  to  say,  we  shall  deal  with  the  tasks  of  the  gov- 
ernmental executive  on  the  agency  level,  whatever  the  name  of  the  agency. 
Names  differ  widely  today.  Aside  from  the  regular  departments — federal, 
state  and  local — we  find  agencies  labeled  as  offices  (such  as  the  Office  of 
Price  Administration),  administrations  (such  as  the  Veterans  Administra- 
tion), authorities  (such  as  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority),  and  so  on. 
Quite  a  few  of  these  are  permanent  establishments;  many  others  are  of  an 
emergency  character.  However  they  may  differ  in  durability,  most  of  them 
are  generically  very  much  like  the  regular  departments.  Their  heads  face 
about  the  same  working  conditions  and  tribulations. 

External  Affairs.  Like  the  chief  executive  himself,  the  governmental 
executive  on  the  agency  level  must  cope  with  two  main  categories  of  busi- 
ness: external  matters  and  internal  matters.  Both  categories  compete  for 
his  attention.  He  cannot  safely  neglect  the  one  for  the  other.  In  this  re- 
spect, again,  the  governmental  executive  finds  himself  in  a  position  not 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  199 

basically  different  from  that  occupied  by  the  executive  in  private  enterprise. 
It  is  sometimes  suggested  that  the  governmental  executive,  being  a  public 
figure  distinctly  visible  to  the  public,  is  more  heavily  burdened  with  ex- 
ternal matters.  However,  private  management  has  recently  become  very 
much  aware  of  the  necessity  for  dividing  its  energy  to  satisfy  the  general 
public  as  well  as  its  customers,  stockholders,  and  employees. 

An  angry  general  public  can  stir  up  a  lot  of  trouble  even  for  the  biggest 
corporations.  Thus  it  is  sound  protection  of  investment  for  private  man- 
agement to  put  its  best  foot  forward  in  its  relations  with  the  general  public. 
Ever  since  the  late  Ivy  Lee  made  himself  the  father  of  a  new  profession 
by  "humanizing"  the  Pennsylvania  Railroad  and  the  senior  Rockefeller, 
the  art  of  public  relations  has  enjoyed  top  rating  among  the  external  con- 
cerns of  business  executives.  The  emergence  of  such  figures  as  Archibald 
MacLeish,  a  ranking  man  of  letters,  and  William  Benton,  a  publicity 
specialist,  as  Assistant  Secretaries  of  State  in  charge  of  informational  services 
is  symptomatic  of  the  same  development  in  public  administration. 

Roughly  speaking,  the  weight  of  the  executive  function  in  the  technical 
sense  rests  in  the  internal  realm,  in  the  direction  of  an  administrative  or- 
ganization toward  accomplishment  of  its  purposes.  By  comparison,  ex- 
ternal business  gives  the  impression  of  being  auxiliary  to  the  executive 
function,  providing  for  the  surrounding  conditions  under  which  this  func- 
tion— and  the  total  task  of  the  organization — can  best  be  carried  out.  Such 
a  distinction,  however,  should  not  lead  us  to  assume  that  we  may  draw  a 
precise  borderline  between  external  and  internal  aspects.  Quite  apart  from 
questions  of  administrative  policy  where  public  repercussions  are  often  a 
crucial  factor,  even  seemingly  innocent  details  of  management  have  an 
alarming  capacity  for  catching  unexpected  attention  outside  the  agency's 
four  walls.  Most  problems  which  come  before  the  governmental  execu- 
tive carry  with  them  potentialities  of  public  debate,  and  require  at  least 
a  second  thought  from  this  angle. 

Living  in  a  Goldfish  Bowl.  Fortunately,  the  large  majority  of  items 
passing  across  the  desk  of  the  governmental  executive  fail  to  attract  outside 
notice.  But  he  can  never  be  sure  in  advance.  Newsmen  have  their  peculiar 
pipelines.  Congressmen  fish  up  a  great  many  interesting  things  about  regu- 
lations, instructions,  and  orders  which  agency  field  officials  bring  to  bear 
upon  constituents  "back  home."  Grilling  may  be  merciless  when  the  time 
comes  around  for  legislative  committee  hearings  on  the  agency's  budgetary 
estimates,  to  say  nothing  about  investigating  committees. 

Of  course,  public  wakefulness  is  not  only  necessary  in  a  democracy  but 
also  a  most  desirable  stimulant.  Yet  the  governmental  executive  frequently 
has  a  tough  time  trying  to  do  anything  without  offending  some  organized 
group  or  running  up  against  the  highly  personal  views  of  a  powerful  fig- 
ure in  the  legislature.  On  the  legitimate  doctrine  that  public  business  is 
everybody's  business,  we  are  as  a  nation  predisposed  toward  criticizing  pub- 


200  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

lie  officials  more  liberally  and  spontaneously  than  we  do  executives  in 
private  enterprise.  That  in  itself  has  done  much  to  retard  the  demise  of  the 
myth  that  business  management  is  more  efficient  than  government,  and  to 
keep  alive  the  dangerous  notion  that  the  price  of  democracy  is  inefficiency. 

Because  of  the  pressure  of  external  matters,  the  governmental  executive 
must  be  something  of  a  politician,  at  least  in  an  extracurricular  way.  If 
he  was  recruited  from  the  arena  of  politics,  he  may  not  find  it  difficult 
to  retain  his  former  alignments  and  friends.  These  are  valuable  sources  of 
counsel  on  matters  of  agency  strategy  and  tactics.  They  can  be  instrumental 
in  promoting  the  public  reputation  of  the  governmental  executive  as  a 
"crack  administrator,"  even  if  his  management  staffs  will  never  cease  to 
shake  their  heads  in  privacy.  Friends  good  and  true,  in  the  legislature  and 
in  interest  organizations,  are  also  able  to  carry  the  ball  for  him  when  the 
game  becomes  fast.  A  different  situation  usually  presents  itself  to  the  gov- 
ernmental executive  whose  rise  to  office  stems  from  eligibility  acquired 
outside  politics  in  the  customary  meaning.  He  needs  the  same  kind  of 
external  support,  but  he  seldom  gets  it  without  extensive  effort.  He  may 
also  learn  that  it  is  not  a  simple  thing  to  be  a  politician  in  an  extracurricular 
fashion  without  making  it  a  curriculum. 

Whatever  the  background  of  the  governmental  executive,  he  cannot  for 
any  length  of  time  relax  his  vigilance  over  his  agency's  public  relations. 
This  requires  special  internal  organization,  technical  assistance  within  his 
own  office,  and  much  hard  labor  on  his  part  in  mingling  socially  with  the 
right  crowd,  in  building  good  will  at  his  press  conferences,  and  in  cultivating 
his  legislative  contacts.  Nor  should  we  forget  his  equally  exacting  chore  of 
maintaining  himself  close  to  the  chief  executive  and  those  who  have  his 
ear — officials  or  members  of  the  "kitchen  cabinet,"  which  may  also  include 
elements  of  the  distaff  side. 

Finally,  there  are  his  colleagues  at  the  helm  of  various  other  agencies. 
Some  of  them  may  have  sharply  competitive  instincts.  Others  may  demon- 
strate personal  antagonism.  But  rare  is  the  agency  which  can  live  by  itself, 
without  dependence  on  sympathetic  cooperation  from  other  agencies.  It 
would  be  very  bold  to  presuppose  the  existence  of  whole-hearted  cooper- 
ation among  all  members  of  the  executive  family.  In  the  development  of 
cooperation,  the  way  in  which  the  governmental  executive  personally  gets 
along  with  his  brethren  is  a  matter  of  great  importance.  One  of  his  most 
obvious  tasks  as  the  responsible  head  of  his  organization  is  to  exert  himself 
continually  toward  driving  into  every  part  of  it  a  thorough  appreciation 
of  the  need,  not  only  for  good  public  relations,  but  also  for  effective  work- 
ing relationships  with  other  elements  of  the  executive  branch. 

Character  of  Executive  Function.  Turning  to  the  executive  function  itself, 
we  may  describe  its  core  in  brevity  as  direction  and  control— the  former  in  the 
sense  of  providing  for  the  right  kind  of  action,  and  the  latter  looking  toward 
ttie  attainment  of  accountability  for  and  in  the  execution  of  policy.  These 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  201 

two  central  terms  embrace  a  variety  of  integral  and  interrelated  functions. 
Direction  entails  planning,  coordination,  and  programming— even  research. 
Control  involves  organization,  supervision,  documentation,  and  reporting. 
Other  subsidiary  functions  play  in  equal  proportions  in  both  spheres. 
Budgeting,  for  instance,  is  simultaneously  a  tool  of  planning  and  a  method 
of  accountability.  Personnel  administration  also  serves  both  direction  and 
control. 

While  there  are  different  ways  of  grouping  the  ingredients  of  the  execu- 
tive function,  no  grouping  can  dispose  of  the  plain  fact  that  the  governmental 
executive  himself  operates  in  a  relatively  small  circle  concentric  with  that 
of  the  total  executive  function.  In  other  words,  in  exercising  the  executive 
function  he  is  at  the  pole  from  which  his  actions  radiate  into  his  agency. 
However,  in  shaping  his  actions  and  in  securing  compliance  throughout  the 
agency  he  must  necessarily  rely  on  many  aides  who  thus  act  as  extensions 
of  the  executive  function.  Because  human  beings  are  anything  but  robots, 
these  aides  perform  their  tasks  not  as  inanimate  cogs  but  as  individuals 
who  exert  measurable  influences  upon  one  another,  and  also  upon  the  gov- 
ernmental executive  himself.  This  makes  the  latter  a  more  resourceful  and 
better  informed  chief.  But  it  is  at  the  same  time  a  control  and  a  limitation 
placed  upon  him. 

Classes  of  Executive  Aides.  The  aides  who  share  in  the  exercise  of  the 
executive  function  fall  into  fairly  distinct  classes.  They  may  be  divided 
broadly  into  political  and  professional  officers.  Typically,  undersecretaries, 
assistant  secretaries  and  special  assistants  are  political  appointees,  though 
their  claim  to  recognition  is  based  in  an  increasing  number  of  cases  on 
evidence  of  special  competence  rather  than  on  obligations  of  patronage. 
One  or  the  other  may  even  have  come  from  the  ranks  of  the  department. 
The  professional  element  is  mostly  supplied  through  career  service.  In 
federal  administration,  the  majority  of  bureau  chiefs  or  heads  of  special 
services  like  budgeting  have  reached  their  level  from  below;  this  would 
not  be  true  of  many  state  and  local  governments. 

Most  of  the  federal  bureaus  are  in  charge  of  defined  departmental  ac- 
tivities of  a  line  character.  But  you  can  never  trust  official  nomenclature. 
Outstanding  examples  of  bureaus  serving  in  a  staff  capacity  are  the  Bureau 
of  Agricultural  Economics  in  the  Department  of  Agriculture  and  the 
Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics  in  the  Labor  Department.  Many  other  staff 
units  are  known  as  offices,  divisions,  or  branches.  Such  staff  and  auxiliary 
facilities — planning,  management,  budget,  statistics,  personnel — add  to  the 
infusion  of  professional  thinking  into  the  institutional  environment  in  which 
the  agency  head  spends  his  days. 

Attaining  an  Institutional  Product.  The  governmental  executive  thus 
enjoys  the  advantage  of  having  at  his  call  not  only  various  types  of  advisers 
but  also  a  profitable  blend  of  judgments — political  and  professional,  staff 
and  line,  general  and  special.  If  he  is  alert  in  securing  the  proper  mixture 


202  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

for  each  different  occasion,  he  will  rarely  make  a  fool  of  himself.  However, 
the  proper  mixture  cannot  be  found  in  any  book  of  recipes.  The  crux  of 
the  executive  function  lies  therefore  in  the  teamplaj  of  all  the  aides  who 
enter  into  the  exercise  of  direction  and  control. 

In  an  agency  that  has  settled  down  to  its  business  and  has  become  a 
going  concern,  teamplay  will  arise  without  requiring  constant  prodding 
from  the  head  of  the  agency.  Notwithstanding  personal  incompatibilities 
of  one  kind  or  another,  the  individual  members  of  the  team  will  come  to 
adjust  themselves  to  a  pattern  familiar  to  all.  Each  will  learn  the  modes  of 
thought  of  the  others,  including  their  idiosyncrasies  and  their  blow-up 
points.  As  this  process  continues,  the  governmental  executive  will  be  able 
increasingly  to  restrict  himself  to  feeding  fresh  ideas  into  the  team  and  to 
getting  conclusions  into  concrete  form  for  practical  application.  It  is  in  this 
sense  that  some  students  of  management  have  spoken  of  the  executive  as 
the  catalyst  or  as  the  ratifier  of  staff  judgment.  This  is  quite  different  from 
the  nai've  conception  of  the  titan  who  roars  orders. 

Departmental  leadership,  then,  calls  for  much  more  than  a  chief  who 
thinks  of  himself  as  a  ruler  and  "gets  things  going."  He  cannot  whip  sub- 
ordinates into  doing  well.  He  cannot  overrule  them  blindly.  He  has  no 
way  of  preventing  his  orders  from  being  bent  and  twisted  at  will  in  the 
process  of  execution  by  operating  officials  who  say  they  "didn't  understand 
them."  The  governmental  executive — in  widening  the  horizon  of  his  or- 
ganization, in  holding  it  to  its  main  goals,  in  welding  its  resources  together, 
in  straightening  out  internal  and  external  difficulties — shows  himself  a  true 
leader  by  being  ever  mindful  of  the  human  factor.21  The  more  he  suc- 
ceeds in  persuading,  the  less  will  he  be  driven  to  empty  gestures  of  authority. 
In  the  long  run,  his  accomplishments  will  not  stand  up  if  they  fail  to  live 
in  the  minds  and  attitudes  of  his  subordinates.  This  means  that  he  may 
have  to  accept,  at  least  temporarily,  the  veto  of  his  key  officials.  Nor  can 
he  push  ahead  in  too  many  directions  at  once.  He  must  have  considerable 
patience  in  making  his  influence  felt.  Only  thus  can  he  educate  his  or- 
ganization to  think  and  act  on  his  terms.  Only  thus  can  he  give  real  force 
to  his  leadership. 

4.  THE  BUREAU  PATTERN 

Special  Concerns  Versus  General  Purposes.  Exercise  of  the  executive 
function  employs  many  more  individuals  than  the  agency  head  himself. 
Despite  such  relief  as  may  be  achieved  through  distribution  of  responsibili- 
ties among  officials  sharing  in  the  application  of  directive  power  or  im- 
plementing the  directive  power  by  staff  work,  the  governmental  executive 

21  For  a  more  extensive  discussion  of  the  working  approach  of  agency  heads,  see  Stone, 
Donald  C.,  "Notes  on  the  Governmental  Executive:  His  Role  and  His  Methods,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  210  ff.;  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  ch.  7, 
"Operating  on  One's  Proper  Level,"  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  203 

is  still  heavily  burdened.  He  alone  is  able  to  attend  to  the  necessary  con- 
tacts with  the  chief  executive,  legislative  leaders,  and  his  colleagues  in  the 
departmental  system.  He  alone  is  in  a  position  to  reconcile  in  binding 
terms  political  answerability  for  the  actions  of  his  agency  with  vigorous 
pursuit  of  agency  programs.  He  alone  can  shoulder  the  task  of  keeping 
fresh  in  all  minds  a  unified  conception  of  purpose  and  approach. 

Faced  with  these  prime  duties,  he  would  invite  failure  and  defeat  if  he 
allowed  his  energies  to  be  dissipated  in  details  and  trivialities.  Of  course, 
small  things  are  often  more  important  than  they  seem  to  be  at  first  glance, 
especially  if  they  have  a  political  twist.  In  trying  to  shun  small  things,  the 
governmental  executive  therefore  cannot  afford  to  dispose  of  sage  discrimi- 
nation. He  must  develop  an  eye  for  the  significant  detail.  Yet  he  should 
normally  stick  to  his  proper  level.  If  he  does  not,  he  is  likely  not  only 
to  give  inadequate  time  to  his  main  role  but  also  to  befuddle  his  supporting 
cast  and  throw  working  relationships  on  lower  levels  out  of  gear. 

In  confining  himself  generally  to  his  own  level,  the  governmental  execu- 
tive would  have  little  ease  of  mind  if  he  could  not  be  reasonably  sure  of 
the  caliber,  loyalty,  and  thought  processes  of  his  key  subordinates.  This 
again  underscores  one  of  his  principal  obligations — that  of  establishing  close 
rapport  with  the  subleadership  of  his  organization  so  that  his  attitude  can 
become  active  on  a  broad  scale.  Subordinates  can  directly  handle  many 
issues  when  they  know  of  his  general  attitude.  They  can  evolve  a  pretty 
dependable  sense  of  differentiation  in  determining  what  matters  should  go 
up  to  him  and  what  matters  they  can  settle  in  their  spheres. 

It  is  difficult  to  spell  out  such  differentiation  in  writing,  but  in  the  work- 
ing style  of  a  well-directed  agency  the  differentiation  is  usually  quite  pre- 
cise to  all  concerned.  Equally  important  is  the  willingness  of  the  govern 
mental  executive  to  make  the  most  of  his  associates  by  handing  them  things 
that  are  too  tough  for  him  to  accomplish  without  assistance.  He  is  the  con- 
ductor in  the  concert  of  specialists;  as  such  he  needs  only  his  score,  a  baton, 
and  the  eyes  of  his  orchestra.  When  technicalities  come  up,  he  should 
promptly  turn  them  over  to  his  technicians.  When  operational  questions 
arise,  he  should  first  put  them  up  to  his  operators.  In  either  case,  he  has 
to  be  familiar  with  the  structure  of  his  resources. 

Centrifugal  Pull.  Most  of  the  staff  and  auxiliary  services  aiding  the 
governmental  executive  are  appendages  to  his  own  office,  though  the  organi- 
zation chart  will  show  them  as  separate  boxes.  But  the  operating  branches, 
traditionally  organized  as  bureaus  or  their  equivalent,  are  one  further  step 
removed.  Each — in  its  divisions,  sections,  units,  and  field  establishments — 
may  control  many  hundreds  and  even  thousands  of  employees.  And  the 
number  of  such  bureaus  within  one  agency  may  run  to  a  score.  The 
sheer  bulk  of  these  operating  branches  absorbed  in  their  particular  business 
means  for  the  agency's  center— the  secretary's  level— an  enormous  centrifu- 
gal pull,  a  constant  "downward  drag."  As  one  able  former  undersecretary 


204  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

has  remarked,  "throughout  my  stay  in  Washington  I  have  been  impressed 
with  the  fact  of  too  great  separation  on  the  part  of  the  bureaus  from 
the  departments."22 

This  separation  is  not  simply  overcome  by  placing  groups  of  bureaus  in 
charge  of  assistant  secretaries  or  coordinating  directors.  However,  we  can 
see  the  obvious  need  for  "some  collateral  or  parallel  lines  of  control  to  push 
against  the  whole  vertical  structures  of  the  bureaus  in  moving  the  bureaus 
into  closer  association  and  harmony."  In  addition,  "immediately  around  the 
secretary  there  must  be  a  special  means  for  converting  matters  that  come 
from  the  special  bureau  pyramids  into  the  general."23  During  World  War 
II  as  well  as  earlier,  the  Department  of  Agriculture  experimented  with  ar- 
rangements of  this  kind,  if  only  in  a  tentative  fashion.  Such  arrangements, 
however,  do  not  yield  results  automatically.  They  are  stepping  stones  that 
lead  to  varying  degrees  of  functional  integration  when  and  insofar  as  the 
departmental  officialdom  can  be  induced  to  use  them  as  the  customary  and 
the  safest  thing  to  do. 

Bureau  Intransigence.  As  departments  are  prone  to  struggle  for  their 
operational  prerogatives  and  find  inconspicuous  ways  of  defying  or  evading 
central  control,  so  bureaus  within  departments  prefer  to  be  "left  alone"  by 
the  departmental  high  command.  Some  of  this  tendency  is  everpresent.  It 
is  frequently  reenforced  by  bureau  self-sufficiency,  both  in  squarely  sitting 
on  a  special  function  and  in  holding  hands  with  a  specific  clientele.  The 
result  may  be  a  high  degree  of  institutional  intransigence  paired  with  sub- 
servience to  interest  demands  coming  from  the  outside.  The  one  is  as  em- 
barrassing to  the  governmental  executive  as  the  other. 

Here,  as  in  the  area  of  the  chief  executive,  we  can  notice  distinctly  the 
unintended  consequences  of  the  historic  growth  of  our  administrative  organ- 
ization. The  body  administrative  first  developed  its  extremities,  then  its 
head.  In  their  relative  proportions,  hands  and  feet — the  operating  extremi- 
ties— are  oversized  and  the  control  center  of  the  nervous  system  is  still  too 
weak.  To  change  the  metaphor,  the  relationship  between  the  bureaus  and 
the  secretary's  setup  resembles,  more  often  than  it  should,  the  proverbial 
tail  wagging  the  dog. 

Weight  of  Professionalization  on  Bureau  Level.  The  genesis  of  our 
administrative  system  is  also  reflected  in  a  related  fact.  Not  only  are  the 
staff  facilities  available  to  the  governmental  executive  younger  and  weaker 
than  most  of  the  operating  bureaus;  they  are  also  less  representative  of  the 
career  element!24  Thus  general  management  and  control,  in  terms  of  the 

22Appleby,  Paul  H.,  in  an  interesting  exchange  of  letters  with  Professor  Arnold  Brecht 
published  in  Public  Administration  Review,  1942,  Vol.  2,  p.  63. 

23  fad.,  p.  66. 

24  A  most  valuable  source  of  information  on  this  and  related  subjects  is  Macmahon,  Arthur 
W.  and  Millett,  John  D.,  federal  Administrators,  New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1939. 
See  also  the  first  author's  earlier  studies  of  selection  and  tenure  of  federal  bureau  chiefs  pub- 
lished in  American  Political  Science  Review,  1926,  Vol.  20,  p.  548  ff.t  770  if. 


THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM  205 

entire  department,  have  to  contend  with  a  greater  measure  of  professionali- 
zation  on  the  lower  levels.  The  answer,  of  course,  is  fuller  recognition  of 
the  career  idea  near  the  apex  of  the  administrative  hierarchy,  including  a 
differentiation  between  political  and  permanent  members  of  the  secretary's 
entourage. 

It  is  interesting  that  the  central  departments  in  Germany,  where  the 
career  principle  for  the  higher  service  emerged  more  than  two  centuries  ago, 
have  traditionally  operated  as  very  small  establishments,  with  the  operating 
branches  organized  as  autonomous  though  subordinate  entities.  The  depart- 
ment head  exercised  his  authority  primarily  through,  or  with  the  constant 
counsel  of,  his  permanent  undersecretary.  The  permanent  undersecretary 
in  turn  relied  on  the  directors  of  some  three  to  five  divisions,  each  of  which 
was  composed  of  less  than  a  dozen  officers,  not  counting  clerical  personnel. 
These  officers — principals,  as  their  counterpart  is  called  in  British  minis- 
terial parlance — looked  after  their  special  fields,  in  which  each  was  "ex- 
pected to  be  the  foremost  expert  of  the  country,  at  least  so  far  as  it  relates  to 
government."25  The  principals  were  the  links  between  the  department  and 
its  autonomous  though  subordinate  bureaus  headed  by  presidents.  The 
individual  principal  kept  the  bureaus  under  his  jurisdiction  in  touch  with 
departmental  policy  and  conversely  received  all  necessary  information  from 
them.  This  may  appear  to  us  as  a  still  more  marked  separation  of  the  bu- 
reaus from  the  departments.  Actually,  conversion  of  business  from  the 
special  bureau  context  to  the  general  departmental  context  was  more  easily 
attained  through  a  small  but  high-powered  top  organization  composed  of 
career  men. 

Reaffirming  Unity  of  Purpose.  However,  although  his  bureaus  may 
have  assertive  individualities  of  their  own,  it  should  not  be  inferred  that  the 
governmental  executive  is  helpless  in  the  face  of  subtle  obstinacy.  His  staff 
and  auxiliary  services,  if  alive  to  their  opportunities,  are  capable  of  acting 
for  him  at  many  points  of  the  departmental  organization  in  the  combined 
roles  of  mediators,  missionaries,  and  watchdogs.  The  departmental  budget 
officer,  for  example,  can  be  extremely  useful  in  keeping  operating  bureaus 
in  line  by  screening  their  requests  for  appropriations  with  a  view  to  con- 
formity with  the  general  program  of  the  agency  head.  Nor  need  the  pres- 
sure for  synthesis  come  exclusively  from  the  top.  Interbureau  committees 
may  be  utilized  to  provide  gentle  compulsion  for  the  operating  services  to 
take  account  of  a  broader  conception  than  that  of  their  own  cherished 

25Brecht,  Arnold  and  Glascr,  Comstock,  The  Art  and  Technique  of  Administration  in 
German  Ministries,  p.  25,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1940.  Professor  Brecht,  a 
former  ministerial  director  in  the  German  career  service,  has  argued  the  case  for  arrangements 
described  in  the  text  in  a  number  of  thoughtful  statements,  most  extensively  in  his  article  on 
"Smaller  Departments,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  363  ff.,  and  in  some 
subsequent  correspondence  with  Mr.  Appleby,  then  undersecretary  in  the  Department  of  Agri- 
culture, he.  cit.  above  in  note  22,  p.  61  ff.  It  is  pertinent  to  observe  that  federal  departments 
have  as  a  rule  met  suspicion  on  the  part  of  the  Appropriations  Committees  of  Congress  when 
proposing  reinforcement  of  the  immediate  organization  at  the  disposal  of  the  department  head. 


206  THE  DEPARTMENTAL  SYSTEM 

microcosm.26  Consultative  methods,  systematically  applied,  can  contribute 
substantially  to  the  formation  of  what  may  justly  be  called  the  depart- 
mental mind.  Regular  staff  conferences,  bringing  together  responsible  offi- 
cials on  various  levels  of  the  departmental  pyramid,  offer  another  device 
that  has  yielded  tangible  benefits  where  it  has  found  thoughtful  sponsorship 
and  intelligent  support. 

To  be  sure,  forms  of  administrative  structure  and  management,  though 
experience  may  favor  one  over  another,  are  never  better  than  the  living  sub- 
stance for  which  they  are  to  serve  as  receptacles.  This  living  substance  is 
made  up  of  men  and  women  who  at  best  represent  humanity  in  all  of  its 
embodiments.  That  they  have  passed  entrance  examinations  is  perhaps  the 
least  significant  thing  about  them.  Much  more  important,  beyond  their 
quest  of  decent  living,  is  their  pride  of  service  and  the  nature  of  their  adjust- 
ment to  the  discipline  of  working  together  for  an  end  above  personal  gain. 
In  both  their  pride  and  their  adjustment,  they  are  subject  to  influences — 
good  and  bad — that  spring  from  the  dynamics  of  our  political  order.  Depart- 
mental leadership  is  only  one  of  these  influences,  but  its  effects  should  not 
be  underestimated.  The  more  we  succeed  through  proper  staffing  in  making 
departmental  leadership  an  institutional  product,  the  less  need  we  fear  the 
bungling  or  bullying  of  uninspired  mediocrity. 

2<JFor  the  experience  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  which,  has  extensively  relied  on 
this  medium,  see  Glaser,  Comstock,  "Managing  Committee  Work  in  a  Large  Organization," 
Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  249  ff.  See  also  in  general  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz, 
"Bureaucracy  and  Consultation,"  Review  of  Politics,  1939,  Vol.  1,  p.  84  ff.,  and  "Policy  Formu- 
lation and  the  Administrative  Process,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1939,  Vol.  33,  p. 


CHAPTER 


Independent  Regulatory  Establishments 

The  administrative  structure  of  government  is  often  pictured  as  a  neatly 
symmetrical  pyramid  in  which  each  stone  is  a  unit  of  the  executive  branch 
and  the  capstone  is  the  chief  executive.  Tidy  instincts  make  us  expect  that 
no  stray  stones  will  be  scattered  about  on  the  ground  surrounding  the  pyra- 
mid. In  practice,  government  is  not  organized  that  way,  and  there  is  a 
considerable  body  of  opinion  that  it  should  not  be  so  organized.  We  need 
only  glance  at  any  government  in  this  country  or  abroad  to  see  that  while 
many  public  agencies  are  subject  to  immediate  control  by  the  chief  execu- 
tive, there  are  a  number  of  agencies  having  some  degree  of  independence 
from  him  and  even,  in  certain  cases,  from  the  legislature.  It  is  these  so- 
called  independent  establishments  that  will  receive  particular  attention  in 
the  present  chapter. 

1.  TYPES  OF  INDEPENDENT  ESTABLISHMENTS 

Meaning  of  Independence.  "Independence,"  as  a  word,  has  acquired  a 
confusing  variety  of  meanings  in  the  governmental  setting.  Usually  the 
word  refers  to  freedom  of  an  agency  from  immediate  control  by  the  chief 
executive  and,  in  some  cases,  by  the  legislature.  In  certain  uses,  however, 
"independence"  in  government  refers  to  integrity  and  devotion  to  the  public 
interest — &  natural  derivative  from  the  first  meaning  if  legislatures  and  chief 
executives  are  thought  of  as  "political"  in  the  opprobrious  sense  of  that  term. 
By  natural  progression,  this  emphasis  on  integrity  and  the  public  interest  as 
the  very  substance  of  independence  leads  to  giving  "independence"  the 
meaning  of  freedom  from  control  by  special  interest  groups.  Sometimes 
even,  by  independence  is  meant  an  agency's  freedom  to  act  without  fear 
of  highly  restrictive  legal  barriers  erected  by  courts  of  law.  Finally,  those  who 
use  independence  in  the  sense  of  freedom  from  executive  and  legislative  con- 
trol may  wind  up,  through  a  different  chain  of  reasoning,  with  an  "inde- 
pendence" that  means  direct  responsibility  to  the  electorate. 

These  confusions  of  meaning  are  not  so  great  as  to  create  insuperable 

207 


208  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

obstacles  to  consideration  of  the  status  of  so-called  independent  establish- 
ments. Actually,  they  arise  simply  from  applying  the  same  term  to  two 
things.  The  first  is  the  end  sought— the  formulation  and  administration  of 
public  policies  without  undue  pressure  from  political  and  economic  inter- 
ests. The  second  is  the  supposed  means  to  that  end — the  organizational 
status  of  "independence"  or  isolation  from  political  and  economic  centers 
of  power. 

There  are  five  main  types  of  agencies  for  which  independent  status  is 
often  urged  and  obtained.  First  are  the  regulatory  agencies,  charged  with 
exercising  broad  governmental  powers  in  connection  with  electric  power, 
transportation,  insurance,  banking,  liquor  control,  securities  issuance,  fair 
trade  practices,  labor  relations,  radio,  and  other  important  economic  areas. 
The  second  type  is  the  government-in-business  enterprise,  usually  organized 
as  the  government  corporation,  to  which  the  next  chapter  is  specifically 
addressed.  Third  are  certain  service  agencies.  Some  of  these,  like  educa- 
tional institutions  and  welfare  departments,  may  claim  the  right  to  inde- 
pendence largely  because  of  the  professionalization  of  their  staffs.  Others, 
like  highway  commissions  and — to  some  extent — social  agencies,  claim 
independence  because  of  the  possibility  of  the  governor's  making  political 
capital  of  their  large  staffs  and  expenditures.  The  fourth  group  consists  at 
the  state  level  of  such  officials  as  the  state  treasurer,  secretary  of  state,  and 
attorney  general,  who  largely  for  traditional  and  political  reasons  may  be 
directly  responsible  to  the  electorate.  Finally,  there  are  the  auditors  who, 
because  they  are  expected  to  report  independently  on  the  legality  of  expendi- 
tures by  executive  officials,  are  wisely  made  independent  of  control  by  the 
chief  executive.1 

Surprisingly,  it  is  genuinely  difficult  to  determine  when  an  agency  is 
independent.  In  fact,  both  complete  independence  from,  and  complete 
subordination  to,  the  chief  executive  and  the  legislature  are  myths.  All 
governmental  institutions  draw  too  much  from  the  same  wellspring  of  ideas 
and  are  too  exposed  to  the  same  "climate  of  opinion"  to  be  thought  of  as 
truly  independent  for  long.  Independent  establishments,  like  courts,  follow 
the  election  returns,  though  sometimes  with  considerable  reluctance  and 
delay.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  a  familiar  feature  of  bureaucracy  that  even 
in  the  more  highly  integrated  executive  branch,  individual  departments, 
bureaus,  and  sections  can  muster  a  considerable  resistance  to  direction  by 
superior  authority;  this  can  be  remedied  only  by  firm  and  decisive  action 
by  the  higher  executives.  We  are,  therefore,  dealing  with  a  matter  of 
degree — greater  or  lesser — of  independence,  not  with  complete  independ- 
ence or  complete  dependence. 

1In  the  federal  government  the  term  "independent  establishments"  frequently  refers  to 
all  agencies  neither  in  the  legislative  nor  the  judicial  branch  that  are  outside  the  ten  so-called 
executive  departments.  Such  agencies,  including,  for  instance,  the  National  Archives  and  the 
Smithsonian  Institution,  have  very  little  in  common  except  this  one  negative  characteristic,  and 
are  not  as  a  group  the  subject  of  this  chapter. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  209 

Institutional  Safeguards  of  Independence.  Ingenious  designers  have  by 
now  developed  most  of  the  institutional  arrangements  that  promise  to  in- 
crease an  agency's  degree  of  independence.  The  most  common  device  is  that 
of  the  commission  or  board  form  of  organization.  It  is  supposed  that  a 
group  of  three,  five,  or  seven  men  is  less  susceptible  of  subservience  to  the 
chief  executive  than  a  single  department  head.  If  decisions  must  be  made 
by  such  a  multiple-member  commission,  there  is  likely  to  be  emphasis  upon 
discussion,  deliberation,  consideration  of  all  relevant  opinions,  and  com- 
promise. The  very  delay  involved  in  calling  a  formal  meeting  of  the  com- 
mission before  a  decision  is  made  is  an  influence  against  precipitate  com- 
pliance with  the  chief  executive's  orders. 

Conceivably,  of  course,  even  a  commission  could  be  made  subservient  if 
its  members  were  party  loyalists  all  allied  with  the  chief  executive,  or  if 
they  were  beholden  to  him  for  their  tenure  and  could  be  removed  at  any 
time  he  thought  appropriate.  In  fact,  some  commissions  and  boards  are  cre- 
ated as  agents  of  the  chief  executive,  with  no  thought  that  they  will  be  or 
should  be  independent.  Advocates  of  independence  must  therefore  go  be- 
yond mere  creation  of  commissions. 

Many  commissions  must  be  bipartisan;  that  is,  each  must  be  composed  of 
members  of  both  major  political  parties  and  in  approximately  equal  num- 
bers. However,  political  scientists  are  agreed  that  the  requirement  of  bipar- 
tisanship puts  a  premium  on  extensive  political  activity  as  a  qualification 
for  membership,  and  therefore  fails  to  lift  commissions  out  of  politics  into 
an  atmosphere  of  true  independence.2  Furthermore,  with  each  major  party 
at  present  such  a  congeries  of  discordant  factions,  a  bipartisanship  require- 
ment alone  cannot  prevent  a  shrewd  chief  executive  from  picking  a  majority 
of  members  who  share  his  views  on  public  policy  in  the  area  of  the  com- 
mission's responsibility.  While  party  labels  still  mean  different  orientations 
as  to  public  policy  when  applied  to  each  party  as  a  whole,  such  labels  may 
be  quite  meaningless  when  attached  to  individuals. 

Another  supposed  assurance  of  independence  is  the  staggered-term 
arrangement.  Terms  of  members  of  each  commission  are  scheduled  on  an 
overlapping  basis  so  that  no  individual  chief  executive  during  his  term  of 
office  has  an  opportunity  to  appoint  a  majority  of  members  of  any  commis- 
sion. Thus  it  is  assured  that  no  commission  will  be  subservient  to  him. 
This  safeguard  breaks  down  if  the  same  chief  executive  is  elected  for 
more  than  one  term  or  if  the  same  political  party  or  faction  captures 
the  post  of  chief  executive  for  several  terms  in  succession.  Furthermore, 
it  is  to  be  noted  that  not  only  newly  appointed  commissioners  but  also  hold- 

2  One  distinguished  public  servant,  Joseph  B.  Eastman,  nearly  missed  appointment  to  the 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission  because  he  was  an  independent  in  politics  and  hence  could 
not  qualify  clearly  as  a  member  of  either  political  party.  For  convenience,  he  was  classified  as 
a  Republican  since  there  was  no  Democratic  vacancy.  See  Swisher,  Carl  B.,  "Joseph  B»  East- 
man— Public  Servant,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  37  ft. 


210  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

overs  whose  terms  will  expire  during  the  chief  executive's  term  are  likely 
to  be  hospitable  to  his  views  on  policy. 

Appointment  and  Removal  of  Members.  Statutory  or  constitutional 
restriction  on  the  exercise  of  the  executive's  appointive  power  in  connection 
with  commissions  is  another  device  resorted  to  in  the  name  of  independence. 
Many  such  restrictions  are  scarcely  worth  notice,  for  they  are  almost  mean- 
ingless— statutory  insistence  that  an  appointee  be  of  good  moral  character, 
or  have  professional  or  business  experience,  or  be  free  of  a  criminal  record! 
A  requirement  of  senatorial  confirmation  of  appointments  is  difficult  to 
appraise.  Possibly  it  deters  the  chief  executive  from  making  outrageous 
appointments,  though  public  opinion  alone  should  suffice  as  a  check.  On 
the  other  hand,  a  requirement  of  senatorial  confirmation  may  actually 
inject  so  much  politics  into  appointments  as  to  discourage  able  citizens  from 
allowing  themselves  to  be  put  forward  as  candidates  for  public  positions. 
Sometimes  the  chief  executive's  freedom  of  choice  is  considerably  restricted 
by  the  requirement  that  he  select  appointees  from  a  limited  panel  of  names 
prepared  by  some  presumably  nonpolitical  group.  Thus,  neutral  citizens — 
for  example,  presidents  of  the  principal  universities  in  the  state — may  be 
authorized  by  law  to  nominate  to  the  governor  candidates  from  whom  he 
shall  select  members  of  an  important  regulatory  commission. 

In  other  instances,  the  legislature  may  actually  force  the  governor  to 
select  all  commission  members  from  a  panel  of  names  submitted  by  a  single 
special-interest  group.  This,  of  course,  reflects  considerable  distrust  of  the 
governor  and  relatively  greater  confidence  in  the  interest  group's  sympa- 
thetic regard  for  the  public  interest.  Often  such  a  provision  betokens  abdi- 
cation by  the  legislature  in  favor  of  self-regulation  by  an  industry,  profes- 
sion, or  other  economic  group.  Sometimes  several  competing  interest  groups 
are  brought  into  the  nomination  process,  and  the  chief  executive  is  required 
to  select  a  certain  number  of  his  appointees  from  nominees  of  each  of  the 
Interest  groups.  Through  such  a  balancing  of  special  interests  in  its  mem- 
bership it  is  supposed  that  the  commission's  decisions  will  come  close  to 
representing  the  public  interest — a  supposition,  it  may  be  added,  that 
students  should  regard  with  some  skepticism. 

More  importance  is  attached  to  the  removal  power  than  to  any  other 
criterion  of  independence.  Unless  a  commissioner  or  head  of  an  agency  has 
security  of  tenure,  he  is  in  no  position  to  challenge  the  policy  instructions 
of  the  chief  executive.  Actually,  few  statutes  place  commissioners  entirely 
beyond  the  executive's  removal  power.  It  is  recognized  that  legislative  im- 
peachment is  too  cumbersome  a  process  to  be  the  sole  recourse  against 
dishonest  or  inefficient  public  officials.  In  the  case  of  independent  commis- 
sions, however,  the  executive  is  generally  restricted  to  certain  specific  reasons 
for  removal.  "Inefficiency,  neglect  of  duty,  or  malfeasance  in  office"  are 
fairly  customary  grounds  for  removal  in  federal  statutes  creating  independ- 
ent commissions.  These  restrictions  are  enforced  by  the  courts,  as  President 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  211 

Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  found  to  his  sorrow  when,  early  in  the  New  Deal, 
he  attempted  to  remove  Commissioner  William  E.  Humphrey  from  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission.  However,  the  chief  executive  is  allowed  con- 
siderable discretion  in  deciding  what  actions  do  fall  within  the  grounds  for 
removal  specified  by  statute.  Removal  is,  of  course,  an  extreme  step  that  is 
rarely  taken.  Yet  its  existence  or  nonexistence  as  an  ultimate  sanction  of  the 
President's  authority  conditions  the  atmosphere  in  which  commissioners 
consider  his  views  on  commission  policy. 

Financial  Support  and  Basic  Authority.  Freedom  from  reliance  upon  the 
chief  executive  and  the  legislature  for  financial  support  is  an  important 
criterion  of  independence.  We  should  not  underestimate  the  importance 
of  executive  budgets  and  legislative  appropriations  as  annual  or  biennial 
power-bestowing  and  power-withdrawing  instruments — and,  by  natural 
deduction,  instruments  giving  the  chief  executive  and  even  individual 
legislators  an  influence  upon  the  commission  that  they  might  not  have 
otherwise.  Commissions  that  finance  themselves  are  generally  free  of  this 
executive-legislative  type  of  control.  The  Board  of  Governors  of  the  Federal 
Reserve  System  is  supported  directly  by  assessment  upon  the  reserve  banks. 
And  many  state  commissions  on  banking,  insurance,  public  utilities,  agricul- 
tural marketing,  and  professional  licensing  support  themselves  in  whole  or  in 
part  through  assessment  of  fees  on  the  companies  and  individuals  subject  to 
their  regulatory  authority.  As  a  means  to  independence,  financial  support 
is  an  excellent  instrument;  but  it  runs  counter  to  the  whole  emphasis  in 
democratic  history  upon  legislative  possession  of  the  power  of  the  purse. 

As  yet,  the  architects  of  independent  establishments  have  failed  to  free 
such  agencies  from  dependence  on  the  legislative  body  for  grants  of  regu- 
latory authority.  Congress  and  the  state  legislatures  create  and  abolish  the 
powers  of  independent  agencies.  Every  so  often,  therefore,  an  agency,  how- 
ever independent  by  all  the  criteria  just  reviewed,  must  ask  the  legislative 
body  for  extensions  of  its  jurisdiction  and  for  more  effective  sanctions  with 
which  to  enforce  its  decisions.  It  must  also  enter  the  legislative  arena  when- 
ever a  bill  is  proposed  to  abolish  or  weaken  the  agency.3 

Political  Factors.  Two  final  factors  are  important  in  freeing  agencies 
from  dependence  on  the  chief  executive,  even  though  they  are  unrecognized 
by  the  statute  books.  One  is  the  alliance  of  agencies  with  pressure  groups 
whose  economic  and  political  power  is  sufficient  to  protect  their  wards 
against  even  such  controls  as  are  authorized  by  law.  If  a  utilities  commis- 
sion wins  the  favor  of  the  utility  companies,  the  banking  commission  comes 
to  be  regarded  as  the  banks'  creature,  the  fish  and  game  commission  is 
strongly  backed  by  the  well-organized  sportsmen's  associations,  the  labor 

3  A  few  state  agencies  are  established  and  granted  their  powers  by  constitutional  provision; 
dependence  on  the  legislature  is  therefore  lessened,  but  on  occasion  such  agencies  may  have  to 
participate  actively  in  a  campaign  to  influence  an  election  on  proposed  constitutional  amend- 
ments. 


212  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

department  can  run  for  support  to  the  great  labor  organizations,  and 
the  medical  licensing  board  can  turn  to  the  influential  medical  association— 
in  such  situations  a  chief  executive  and  a  legislature  may  readily  be  balked 
in  their  attempts  to  control  these  public  agencies. 

The  second  factor  is  not  unrelated  to  pressure-group  alliances.  It  con- 
cerns the  ability  of  the  agency  to  develop  political  power  sufficient  to  resist 
the  chief  executive's  encroachments  upon  its  independence.  The  courting 
of  pressure  groups  is,  of  course,  a  major  step  in  this  direction.  In  addition, 
if  an  agency  head  controls  a  major  faction  in  the  chief  executive's  political 
party  as  some  agency  heads  are  appointed  in  recognition  of  such  control, 
or  if  the  agency  has  assiduously  cultivated  the  good  will  of  legislators  and 
local  party  leaders,  or  if  the  agency  head  has  established  a  public  prestige 
that  would  cause  the  newspapers,  educational  leaders,  civic  organizations, 
and  women's  clubs  to  protest  vigorously  any  executive  trespassing  on  his 
authority — in  cases  like  these  the  chief  executive  will  not  "cross"  the  agency 
head  without  gauging  accurately  the  political  liabilities  he  might  thereby 
assume. 

In  part,  of  course,  we  are  saying  that  regulation  is  essentially  political, 
that  it  is  concerned  with  the  formulation  of  public  policies.  Over  the  years, 
the  people  have  established  legislative  and  executive  instruments  for  policy- 
making  and  have  placed  emphasis  on  responsiveness  of  those  instruments 
to  public  opinion.  This  responsiveness  is  periodically  enforced  at  the  polls 
and  is  less  formally  emphasized  between  elections  in  newspapers,  corre- 
spondence, speeches,  hearings,  and  through  other  channels.  The  people's 
legislative  and  executive  instruments  must,  in  turn,  control  the  regulatory 
agencies,  unless  we  err  in  speaking  of  the  work  of  these  agencies  as  policy 
formation.  The  problem  may  therefore  in  part  be  reduced  to  the  questions: 
What  is  the  nature  of  regulatory  business?  How  should  it  be  conducted? 

2.  NATURE  AND  CONDUCT  OF  REGULATORY  BUSINESS 

Regulation  is  governmental  circumscribing  of  the  range  of  permissible 
conduct  of  individuals  and  groups.  The  simplest  regulations  require  that 
stop  lights  be  observed,  that  houses  not  be  robbed,  that  children  attend 
school.  In  this  type  of  regulation,  characteristically  the  legislative  body 
adopts  a  clear-cut  rule  defining  public  policy.  It  is  a  simple  task  then  for 
policemen  and  truant  officers  to  arrest  apparent  violators;  and  the  courts 
have  no  serious  problem,  assuming  sufficient  evidence  is  presented,  in  de- 
ciding finally  whether  or  not  the  law  has  actually  been  violated. 

Rule-Making  and  Case-by-Case  Decision.  However,  regulation  by  mod- 
ern government  goes  far  beyond  the  simple  examples  cited.  In  the  less 
simple  types  of  regulation  the  most  dramatic  feature  is  the  extent  to  which 
legislative  bodies  delegate  broad  discretionary  power  to  administrative 
igcncies.  The  legislatures  despair  of  defining  in  crystal-clear  terms  the 
norms  of  conduct  to  govern  economic  or  social  life.  Instead,  they  pass 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  213 

laws  requiring  that  railroad  and  power  rates  be  "just  and  reasonable,"  that 
restaurants  and  dairies  be  "sanitary,"  that  employers  provide  "reasonable 
protection  to  the  lives,  health,  and  safety"  of  their  employees,  that  commer- 
cial practices  not  be  "unfair  or  deceptive"  or  include  "unfair  methods  of 
competition."  The  volume  of  legislative  business,  the  lack  of  expertness 
on  the  part  of  the  average  legislator,  and,  perhaps,  a  disposition  of  the 
lawmaking  body  in  some  instances  to  "pass  the  buck,"  have  all  contributed 
to  the  trend  toward  vague  statutes  whose  only  precision  is  acquired  by 
administrative  and  judicial  action  long  after  the  legislature  has  completed 
its  work.  Whatever  the  cause,  the  administrative  and  judicial  areas  of 
discretion  have  been  vastly  increased  by  legislative  inability  to  define  pre- 
cisely what  acts  government  regards  as  unlawful. 

Once  the  legislature  has  decided  to  delegate  broad  discretionary  authority, 
the  question  of  whether  such  authority  should  be  exercised  through  tech- 
niques of  a  legislative,  judicial,  executive,  or  other  character  is  posed.  Most 
regulatory  agencies  use  a  combination  of  these  approaches,  but  it  is  im- 
portant to  note  the  practical  significance  of  the  several  approaches  because 
the  emphasis  given  each  differs.  If  emphasis  is  placed  on  a  legislative 
technique,  the  agency  will  set  about  doing  what  the  legislature  failed  to  do 
— define  with  some  exactness  the  types  of  acts  that  will  be  treated  as  unlaw- 
ful. This  it  will  do  through  the  issuance  of  rules  and  regulations.  For  ex- 
ample, in  most  states  there  are  industrial  safety  codes,  issued  by  the  state 
labor  department,  which  describe  specifically  the  types  of  safety  precautions 
employers  must  take  if  they  are  to  conform  to  the  legislature's  demand  that 
employers  provide  safe  conditions  of  employment. 

On  the  other  hand,  if  the  discretionary  authority  is  to  be  exercised  along 
judicial  lines,  the  agency  very  probably  will  depend  upon  private  individuals 
to  bring  cases  formally  to  its  attention,  or  it  will  on  its  own  initiative  hail 
suspected  violators  before  its  bar  for  an  investigation,  or  it  will  require 
that  individuals  and  companies  proposing  to  take  a  particular  line  of  action 
— such  as  open  a  liquor  store,  extend  a  railroad's  tracks,  or  practice  medi- 
cine— apply  to  the  agency  for  a  license  or  "certificate  of  convenience  and 
necessity"  before  going  ahead  with  the  proposed  action.  Whichever  of  these 
approaches  is  followed,  the  agency  will  be  deciding  each  case  as  it  comes 
along,  without  paying  too  much  attention  to  the  need  of  industry  and 
citizens  for  more  reliable  guidance  as  to  permissible  conduct  than  either 
the  vague  statute  or  the  spotty  pattern  of  past  case  decisions  affords. 

The  rule-making  approach  does  have  the  advantage  that  the  public  learns 
relatively  more  promptly  the  standards  by  which  it  must  abide.  Further- 
more, in  formulating  such  general  rules,  the  regulatory  agency  can  engage 
in  thorough  research  and  consult  with  representatives  of  all  groups  likely  to 
be  affected  by  the  regulation.  Thereby  the  agency  frankly  acknowledges  that 
it  is  making  public  policy,  that  it  needs  to  inform  itself  of  all  relevant  eco- 
nomic facts,  and  that  it  desires  the  advice  of  all  affected  interests. 


214  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

The  case-by-case  approach,  on  the  other  hand,  leaves  the  public  in  the 
dark  for  years,  in  some  instances,  as  to  what  the  vague  statute  means.  It 
often  narrows  the  evidence  to  that  presented  in  formal  court-like  hearings. 
It  tends  to  ignore  affected  interests  not  represented  by  the  two  contending 
parties  to  each  dispute.  And  it  permits  the  introduction  of  considerations 
of  public  policy  and  public  interest  only  as  rather  regrettable  departures 
from  "sound"  procedure. 

The  case-by-case  approach  reaches  its  greatest  usefulness  when  the  func- 
tion is  genuinely  one  of  settlement  of  disputes  between  two  parties;  as,  for 
example,  when  an  injured  workman  seeks  compensation  from  an  employer. 
Especially  is  this  true  where  the  statute,  or  a  set  of  regulations  having 
the  force  of  law,  fairly  clearly  establishes  the  standards  to  control  the  adjudi- 
cative  work.  What  is  needed  then  is  simply  a  process  that  will:  (1)  let 
the  two  parties  tell  their  stories  and  argue  whether  the  facts  fall  within  or 
without  the  area  defined  by  the  legislative  standards;  and  (2)  ensure  that 
the  decision  is  made  by  a  man  who  will  honestly  weigh  the  evidence  and 
arguments  presented  by  the  two  sides  and  exercise  wise  judgment  in  ruling 
which  contender  should  prevail.  This  clearly  is  a  different  situation  from 
one  where  public  policy  needs  to  be  defined,  where  the  public  interest  needs 
to  be  vigorously  advanced  in  an  industrial  area  in  which  that  interest  has 
previously  been  subordinated  to  private  interests,  and  where  an  important 
segment  of  the  economy  needs  to  know  the  "rules  of  the  game." 

Administrative  Approach.  A  third  approach  to  regulation  is  usually 
thought  of  as  executive  or  administrative  in  character.  Most  clearly  con- 
nected with  this  approach  is  the  regulatory  function  of  inspection.  It  is  the 
inspector  who  checks  fire  precautions  in  theaters  and  office  buildings;  visits 
factories  to  determine  observance  of  industrial  safety  codes  and  laws  govern- 
ing the  employment  of  women  and  children;  looks  over  barber  shops, 
dairies,  and  restaurants  to  ensure  sanitary  conditions;  stops  cars  on  the  high- 
way to  prevent  spread  of  the  Japanese  beetle;  examines  bank  records  to 
protect  depositors  against  loss  of  their  savings;  surveys  factory  payrolls  to 
enforce  wage  and  hour  legislation;  and  goes  through  railway  trains  to  assure 
that  their  equipment  complies  with  all  necessary  safety  devices.  Sometimes 
the  inspector  is  a  laboratory  technician  testing  the  quality  of  food  and  drugs. 
Sometimes,  indeed,  if  the  term  has  a  reasonable  degree  of  elasticity,  he  is  an 
administrator  and  grader  of  examinations  taken  by  candidates  for  licenses 
such  as  doctors,  pharmacists,  and  barbers. 

The  inspector  is  naturally  more  circumscribed  in  his  function  than  an 
agency  head  promulgating  rules  and  regulations  affecting  great  industries; 
the  inspector  is  often  the  implementer  of  such  rules  and  regulations.  Never- 
theless, he  is  no  mere  automaton  answering  "yes"  or  "no"  to  a  form  ques- 
tion as  to  whether  his  inspection  reveals  a  violation.  The  modern  inspector 
is  often  a  missionary,  charged  with  spreading  awareness  and  understanding 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  215 

of  the  law  and  the  administrative  regulations  under  the  law.  He  is  expected 
to  tell  people  subject  to  his  jurisdiction  not  only  what  the  regulations  are 
and  the  penalties  for  their  violation,  but  also  why  the  regulation  is  necessary 
and  deserves  voluntary  compliance.  Inspection  and  enforcement,  in  other 
words,  thrive  best  when  those  subject  to  them  are  so  educated  and  per- 
suaded that  actual  violations  are  few. 

This  very  emphasis  on  the  inspector's  educational  function  lends  breadth 
to  his  discretionary  powers.  For  discovery  of  a  first  violation  is  often  used 
as  an  opportunity  for  an  educational  interview  with  the  violator,  rather  than 
for  punishing  him.  Whether  this  educational  approach  is  followed  twice 
or  thrice  with  the  same  violator,  or  on  the  other  hand  is  rejected  even  for 
a  first  violation  in  favor  of  prompt  punishment,  is  largely  a  matter  for  the 
inspector's  judgment  as  to  which  course  will  best  serve  the  public  interest. 
It  is  noteworthy  that  for  laxity  in  enforcement  by  the  inspector  there  is 
generally  no  judicial  remedy.  The  public  interest,  in  other  words,  is  pro- 
tected only  by  the  administrative  means  of  the  inspector's  removal  or  repri- 
mand by  his  administrative  supervisors. 

Regulatory  officials  and  scholars  alike  have  often  questioned  the  attempts 
to  define  regulatory  approaches  as  either  legislative,  judicial,  or  executive. 
One  basis  of  their  questioning  is  the  frequency  with  which  two  or  three  of 
these  approaches  are  combined  in  the  same  agency.  In  practice  the  rules-and- 
regulations  approach,  which  is  of  a  legislative  character,  and  the  case-by-case 
approach,  which  is  more  judicial  in  orientation,  are  often  found  together. 
For  instance,  in  some  states  the  so-called  workmen's  compensation  board 
both  formulates  industrial  safety  codes  and  hears  individual  cases  of  work- 
men claiming  compensation  for  injuries  sustained  in  industrial  accidents. 
The  War  Production  Board  promulgated  orders  applicable  to  whole  indus- 
tries, heard  appeals  from  individuals  seeking  exemption  from  those  industry- 
wide orders,  and  also  heard  violation  cases.  In  addition,  naturally,  regulatory 
agencies  have  executive  or  administrative  responsibilities.  A  notable  case 
among  the  independent  agencies  is  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission, 
which  enforces  a  variety  of  statutes  designed  to  ensure  safe  operation  of 
the  railroads;  under  one  of  these  statutes  its  inspectors  examine  over  one 
hundred  thousand  locomotives  each  year. 

Mixture  of  Approaches.  In  fact,  the  mixture  of  legislative,  executive, 
and  judicial  approaches  has  been  one  of  the  principal  arguments  for  estab- 
lishment of  the  independent  commissions.  The  reasoning  runs  that,  under 
the  doctrine  of  the  separation  of  powers,  none  of  the  three  great  branches 
of  government  may  exercise  powers  constitutionally  belonging  to  either  of 
the  other  two  branches.  Consequently,  a  regulatory  agency  exercising  a 
combination  of  legislative,  executive,  and  judicial  powers  cannot  constitu- 
tionally belong  to  any  one  of  the  three  branches.  Hence,  the  regulatory 
commissions  must  be  independent.  This  reasoning  overlooks  the  fact  that 


216  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

a  number  of  the  executive  departments  and  agencies  perform  all  three  types 
of  function.4 

The  second  basis  for  questioning  the  attempt  to  categorize  different  types 
of  regulatory  action  as  legislative,  executive,  and  judicial  arises  from  a 
belief  that  this  classification  loses  sight  of  the  real  heart  of  regulation,  which 
is  fact-finding.  It  is  stressed  that  every  major  determination  by  government 
in  the  regulatory  sphere  should  be  preceded  by  an  earnest  effort  to  find  the 
facts.  This  may  involve  broad  research  in  the  economics,  history,  and  ad- 
ministrative phases  of  the  general  problem,  investigation  of  the  records  of 
companies  most  affected  by  the  proposed  decision,  collection  of  statistics 
from  the  industry  on  a  periodic  basis  to  provide  factual  background  for 
all  of  the  agency's  decisions,  and  consultation  with  experts  and  interests 
likely  to  be  directly  or  indirectly  affected  by  the  proposed  decision.  Con- 
sultation might  be  secured  by  formal  hearing,  by  interviews  through  mem- 
bers of  the  agency's  staff,  or  by  correspondence.  It  should  be  directed  to 
getting  both  facts  and  opinions  or  arguments. 

This  is  a  more  comprehensive  approach  than  any  attempt  to  put  regu- 
latory activities  into  neat  packets  labeled  "legislative,"  "executive,"  and 
"judicial"  for  the  purpose  of  using  distinctive  procedures  for  each.  Since  it 
is  convenient  to  argue  by  analogy,  those  who  take  this  fact-finding  approach 
say  that  its  nearest  kin  is  the  approach  of  legislative  committees.5  The 
distinguishing  features  of  the  legislative  committee  are  these:  (1)  it  takes 
the  initiative  in  seeking  economic  and  social  facts  and  opinions  as  a  basis 
for  guiding  the  judgment  of  the  legislative  body;  (2)  it  recognizes  that  in 
pursuing  facts  to  guide  public  policy,  the  cumbersome  procedure  of  law 
courts  would  both  consume  undue  time  and  obstruct  the  assembling  of  rele- 
vant evidence;  (3)  it  works  on  the  assumption  that  its  members  are  the 
seekers  of  the  truth  and  may  take  an  active  part  in  the  questioning  of  wit- 
nesses, without  impairing  each  member's  ability  to  arrive  at  unbiased  judg- 
ments on  the  basis  of  the  facts  and  the  policy  issues  involved;  (4)  it  is  a 
testimonial  to  the  principle  of  delegation,  for  although  the  legislature  itself 


4  Federal    administrative   agencies    exercising   rule-making   and    adjudicative   powers   over 
private  individuals  arc  listed  in  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure, 
Administrative  Procedure  in  Government  Agencies,  p.  261  ff.t  77th  Cong.,   1st  Sess.,  Senate 
Doc.  No.  8,  1941. 

5  An  interesting  feature  in  the  evolution  of  the  independent  commission  is  that  the  earliest 
important  commissions — those  concerned  with  railroad  regulation — were  regarded  as  arms  of 
the  legislative  body  to  investigate  and  recommend  rate-fixing  measures.  Part  of  the  reason  for 
the  adoption  of  procedures  more  like  those  of  courts  than  like  those  of  legislative  committees 
was  probably  the  early  domination  of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  by  Judge  Thomas 
M.  Coolcy,  and  the  initial  appointment  of  no  one  but  lawyers  to  that  commission.   Board  of 
Investigation  and  Research,  Report  on  Practices  and  Procedures  of  Governmental  Control,  p. 
59  ff.,  78th  Cong.,  2d.  Sess.,  House  Doc.  No.  678.  1944. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  217 

makes  the  ultimate  decision,  it  cannot  as  such  take  all  the  evidence  neces- 
sary for  a  sound  decision,  and  instead  relies  on  the  legislative  committee  as 
its  agent,  to  assemble  the  data  and  recommend  appropriate  legislation;  and 
(5)  it  has  an  awareness  that  at  public  hearings  everyone  may  be  represented 
except  the  public,  and  that  in  order  to  guard  resulting  legislation  from 
being  swayed  too  much  by  the  particular  witnesses  and  the  most  vociferous 
special  interests,  the  committee  members  must  themselves  keep  the 
public  interest  constantly  in  mind  in  thinking  through  their  policy 
recommendations. 

In  legislative  committees— as  in  courts,  executive  agencies,  and  independ- 
ent commissions— the  extent  to  which  particular  methods  serve  as  media 
for  arriving  at  sound  decisions  depends  more  upon  the  men  seeking  the 
facts  and  making  the  decisions  than  upon  mechanical  rules  of  procedure. 
Nonetheless,  it  is  apparent  that  a  regulatory  agency  that  followed  the  model 
of  tjie  legislative  committee  would  conduct  itself  differently  from  one  that 
thought  of  itself  as  an  expert  court  for  the  impartial  adjudication  of  contro- 
versies brought  before  it  by  aggrieved  parties. 

Judicial  Control.  This  brings  us  to  the  vital  problem  of  procedures.  One 
startling  aspect  of  the  problem  deserves  special  emphasis.  Although  the 
courts  have  been  very  much  concerned  about  the  procedures  followed  in 
reaching  administrative  decisions  bearing  on  specific  individuals  or  cor- 
porations— that  is,  court-like  decisions — they  have  shown  little  interest  in 
the  question  of  safeguarding  procedures  in  the  formation  of  general  regu- 
latory policy  through  rules  and  regulations.  True,  the  courts  insist  that  legis- 
lative bodies  must  not  completely  abdicate.  They  must  canalize  and  set 
bounds  to  the  discretionary  powers  delegated  to  each  regulatory  agency. 
But  that  hurdle  past,  the  agency  has  been  left  relatively  free  by  the 
courts  to  arrive  at  its  general  rules  and  regulations  by  any  procedure  it 
deems  wise. 

Considerations  of  sound  public  policy  often  dictate  a  democratic  con- 
sultation of  affected  interests  before  a  general  regulation  is  issued.  State 
labor  departments  usually  establish  panels  or  committees  drawn  from  labor 
unions  and  management  to  help  in  drafting  industrial  safety  codes.  The 
United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  has  developed  an  elaborate  system 
of  county  committees  of  farmers  with  whom  questions  of  departmental 
policy  can  be  discussed.  Wartime  agencies,  particularly  the  War  Production 
Board  and  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  used  both  industry  advisory 
committees  and  labor  advisory  committees,  which  were  consulted  in  connec- 
tion with  the  drafting  of  hundreds  of  industry-regulating  orders.  Although 
in  practice  the  formulation  of  rules  and  regulations  is  no  haphazard  dicta- 


218  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

tion  by  uninformed  bureaucrats,  the  courts  cannot  claim  credit  for  this  fact.6 
Their  control  over  the  rule-making  power  stems  from  the  same  roots  as 
their  control  over  the  power  of  legislatures.  That  is  to  say,  the  courts  have 
reviewed  the  substance  of  rules  and  regulations  as  they  have  that  of  laws, 
while  largely  leaving  the  procedures  involved  in  rule-making  to  the  discre- 
tion of  the  administrative  agency.  Rules  and  regulations  have  been  held 
invalid  when  their  provisions  appeared  to  the  courts  either  to  exceed  the 
grant  of  power  made  by  the  legislature  or  to  be  unreasonable  in  terms  of  a 
departure  from  accepted  canons  of  fairness. 

We  have  been  talking  about  rules  and  regulations  of  rather  broad  cover- 
age— usually  a  whole  industry  or  a  large  segment  of  an  industry.  The  courts 
have  whittled  down  procedural  freedom  in  rule-making,  however,  by  insist- 
ing that  where  a  rule,  a  regulation,  or  an  order  was  to  be  quite  specific 
in  its  application— where  it  would,  for  example,  fix  rates  to  be  charged  by 
individual  utilities — something  like  court  procedures  would  be  necessary. 
Here,  curiously,  the  courts  admit  that  rate-fixing  is  a  legislative,  not  a 
judicial  function;  but  nonetheless  they  insist  that  the  procedures  in  rate- 
fixing  be  of  a  judicial  character.7 

Basically  this  means  that  such  rate-determination  must  be  preceded  by 
notice  to  the  affected  parties  and  opportunities  for  them  to  be  heard.  With 
this  principle  established,  the  main  dispute  has  been  over  the  character  of 
the  hearing  that  is  required.  The  courts,  while  always  granting  that  their 
own  rigid  procedures  need  not  be  followed,  have  at  times  imposed  proce- 
dural straitjackets  on  regulatory  departments  and  commissions.  As  a  result 
these  had  to  abandon  many  practices  that  seemed  perfectly  legitimate 
by  analogy  with  administrative  agencies  and  legislative  committees,  espe- 
cially if  we  recall  that  legislatures  may  directly  fix  rates  without  court-like 
procedures.  According  to  one  decision,8  a  full  hearing  involves  the  right  to 
introduce  evidence,  to  know  all  the  evidence  that  is  to  be  considered  by 
the  regulatory  officials  in  fixing  the  rates,  to  have  opportunity  to  refute  that 
evidence—including  the  right  to  cross-examine  witnesses— and  to  have  the 
final  decision  supported  by  substantial  evidence. 

6  Some  statutes  required  notice  and  hearing  prior  to  issuance  of  general  rules  and  regula- 
tions, but  generally  this  was  not  the  case.    The  Walter-Logan  bill,  which  on  the  eve  of  our 
entry  into  World  War  II  nearly  became  law,  included  a  provision  that  "all  administrative  rules 
.  .  .  shall  be  issued  by  the  head  of  the  agency  .  .  .  and  by  each  independent  agency  .  .  .  after 
publication  of  notice  and  public  hearings."   Only  rules  governing  hearing  procedure  itself  were 
to  be  exempted  from  this  blanket  requirement.  The  proposal  was  not  favored  by  the  Attorney 
General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure.   See  Duane,  Morris,  "Mandatory  Hearings  in 
the  Rule-Making  Process,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science, 
1942,  Vol.  221,  pp.  115-122.     The  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of  1946  represents  another 
attempt  at  defining  general  requirements.    For  a  discussion  of  the  main  features  of  this  law, 
sec  below  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 

7  See  Hart,  James,  An  Introduction  to  Administrative  Law,  p.  265,  New  York:    Crofts, 
1940. 

8  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  v.  Louisville  &  Nashville  Railroad  Company,  227  U.  S. 
88  (1913). 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  219 

Even  where  a  hearing  is  initiated  with  the  declared  purpose  of  inquiring 
into  a  particular  company's  rates,  it  has  been  held  inadequate  unless  the 
agency  provides  notice  of  the  specific  rates  it  proposes  to  promulgate,  and 
enables  rebuttal  of  its  proposal.9  Fortunately,  the  courts  have  not  insisted 
that  commissions  and  executive  departments  take  over  wholesale  the  elabo- 
rate rules  of  evidence  that  are  the  lawyer's  stock  in  trade.  We  can  say  "for- 
tunately," having  noted  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission's  statement 
forty  years  ago  that  probably  "not  a  single  case  arising  before  the  Commis- 
sion could  be  properly  decided  if  the  complainant,  the  railroad,  or  the  Com- 
mission were  bound  by  the  rules  of  evidence  applying  to  the  introduction  of 
testimony  in  courts."10 

Of  course,  there  are  cases  of  regulation  where  the  objective  is  similar  to 
that  of  the  courts — a  specific  decision  in  a  case  between  two  private  parties, 
such  as  a  worker  and  his  employer,  or  between  a  government  agency  and 
a  private  party.  In  such  cases,  the  general  principles  of  procedure  applicable 
to  conduct  of  court  business  are  pertinent,  though  softened  by  noninsistence 
upon  rigorous  observance  of  the  rules  of  evidence.  Again,  notice  and 
hearing  are  the  basic  requirements. 

Courts  can  only  set  the  formal  outer  bounds  of  regulatory  procedure. 
Eclipsing  the  importance  of  any  such  judicial  strictures  upon  regulatory 
agencies  are  the  caliber  of  men  given  regulatory  responsibility  and  the 
depth  of  their  understanding  of  the  relation  of  government  to  individual 
citizens  and  enterprises  in  a  democracy.  What  is  required  is  a  positive  de- 
sire for  achievement  of  the  public  interest.  However,  this  desire  must  have 
much  more  balance  than  the  witch-hunting  mood  of  aggressive  public 
prosecutors.  Coincident  with  a  positive  desire  for  achieving  the  public 
interest  must  be  an  understanding  of  the  need  for  avoiding  government 
by  decree  without  advance  consultation  with  affected  interests  and  oppor- 
tunity for  all  relevant  facts  to  be  considered.  Yet  such  understanding  must 
not  lull  the  regulatory  official  into  an  overemphasis  on  individual  rights 
to  the  point  where  the  rights  and  interests  of  the  general  public  are  over- 
looked. The  task  of  devising  regulatory  procedures  that  satisfy  both  public 
and  private  interests  and  are  well  adapted  to  particular  functions  is  a 
challenge  to  legislatures,  courts,  and,  above  all,  the  regulatory  agencies 
themselves.  This  was  clearly  recognized  by  the  Attorney  General's  Com- 
mittee on  Administrative  Procedure. 

Proposals  of  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure. 
The  most  important  inquiry  into  regulatory  procedures  in  recent  years  was 
that  of  the  Attorney  General's  Committee,  which  submitted  its  report  early 
in  1941.  The  committee's  more  significant  recommendations  were  embodied 

9  Morgan  v.  United  States,  304  U.  S.  1  (1938).   See  also  Morgan  v.  United  States,  298 
U.  S.  468  (1936),  where  the  Supreme  Court  insisted  that  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture  per- 
sonally had  to  consider  and  appraise  the  voluminous  evidence  in  a  case  under  the  Packers  and 
Stockyards  Act  before  fixing  rates,  since  the  act  vested  the  rate-fixing  authority  in  him. 

10  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  Annual  Report  for  1908,  p.  10. 


220  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

in  a  bill,  proposed  for  consideration  by  Congress.  We  may  group  them 
under  four  headings.  First  with  respect  to  rule-making,  the  bill  would 
require  extensive  publication  of  policies,  interpretations,  rules,  regulations, 
and  procedures;  annual  reporting  to  Congress  on  rules  issued  by  the  agency 
and  rules  proposed  by  private  citizens;  and  designation  by  each  agency  of 
some  unit  or  official  to  be  responsible  for  keeping  rules  up-to-date  and  for 
receiving  suggestions  from  the  public.  The  bill  would  also  stipulate  a  delay 
of  forty-five  days  between  the  promulgation  of  an  order  and  the  date  it  be- 
comes effective,  subject  to  waiver  by  the  order-issuing  agency.  Second,  with 
respect  to  centralized  governmental  responsibility  for  regulatory  procedures, 
the  bill  would  create  an  Office  of  Federal  Administrative  Procedure,  the  di- 
rector of  which  would  investigate  any  and  all  aspects  of  regulatory  procedure, 
submit  his  recommendations  to  Congress  and  the  individual  agencies,  and 
appoint  hearing  commissioners  to  serve  in  most  regulatory  agencies.  Third, 
the  bill's  major  provision  for  administrative  adjudication  calls  for  the  hold- 
ing of  all  initial  hearings  by  these  hearings  commissioners,  except  where 
agency  heads  themselves  can  hold  all  hearings.  Decisions  of  the  hearing 
commissioners  in  the  cases  they  heard  would  be  final,  unless  appealed  to  the 
agency  heads.  And  fourth,  to  reduce  uncertainty  as  to  whether  proposed 
private  actions  would  be  permitted  by  a  regulatory  agency,  the  bill  would 
authorize  the  issuance  of  declaratory  rulings.  Although  issued  before  alleged 
violation  has  occurred,  these  rulings  would  have  the  same  binding  effect  as 
an  agency  decision  in  an  ordinary  case.  It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  the 
work  of  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  has  had  a  very  beneficial  effect 
on  the  character  and  the  tenor  of  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of 
1946.11 

Worth  noting  is  the  committee's  sympathetic  understanding  and  encour- 
agement of  informal  methods  of  adjudication.  The  committee  observes, 
".  .  .  even  where  formal  proceedings  are  fully  available,  informal  procedures 
constitute  the  vast  bulk  of  administrative  adjudication  and  are  truly  the 
lifeblood  of  the  administrative  process."12  However,  without  detracting  from 
the  utility  of  extensive  reliance  on  informal  procedure  in  appropriate  cases, 
two  facts  should  be  underscored.  In  the  first  place,  adoption  of  informal 
procedures,  involving  bargaining  with  private  interests  in  order  to  arrive 
at  a  mutually  acceptable  course  of  action,  is  often  resorted  to  by  regulatory 
agencies  to  avoid  the  cumbersome  quasi-judicial  procedure  imposed  on  them 
by  courts,  to  get  prompter  compliance  by  the  regulated  interests  instead  of 
the  delays  entailed  in  a  judicial  review  of  a  formal  regulatory  decision,  and 
to  by-pass  the  danger  of  having  the  decision  overturned  by  the  courts.  In 
the  second  place,  cases  settled  by  informal  procedure,  because  of  their  infi- 
nitely greater  volume  than  that  of  formal  cases,  may  sacrifice  the  public 


the  committee's  bill,  see  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  pp.  191-202.  On  the  Adminis- 
trative Procedure  Act  of  1946,  sec  below  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 
12  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  35. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  221 

interest  and  private  rights,  while  on  the  other  hand  lawyers  and  courts  are 
insisting  that  formal  cases  be  settled  with  the  elaborate  paraphernalia  of 
the  courtroom.  This,  of  course,  is  not  to  condemn  informal  procedure. 
It  does,  however,  suggest  the  perils  in  treating  regulatory  procedure  as 
something  concerned  with  cases  of  the  type  that  appear  on  a  law  court's 
docket,  rather  than  as  something  concerned  with,  for  example,  the  hundreds 
of  thousands  of  items  of  business  that  are  handled  annually  by  the  Inter- 
state Commerce  Commission,  mainly  through  its  subordinate  officials. 

The  problem  of  regulatory  procedures  will  never  cease  to  be  perplexing, 
for  it  consists  essentially  of  the  delicate  task  of  achieving  a  balance  between 
public  policy  and  private  rights,  between  form  and  substance,  and  between 
men  and  procedures.  The  problem  is  complicated  by  the  fact  that  this  bal- 
ance is  not  the  same  for  each  regulatory  function.  Procedures  must  be 
adapted  to  the  particular  tasks  assigned  to  regulatory  agencies  by  the 
legislative  body, 

3.  THE  RECORD  OF  INDEPENDENCE 

Regulation  by  Independent  Commissions  and  Executive  Departments. 
In  the  federal  government  the  number  of  independent  regulatory  establish- 
ments has  never  been  large.  Their  significance  results  rather  from  the  im- 
portance of  the  economic  areas  over  which  they  have  jurisdiction  than  from 
their  number.  There  are  only  nine  so-called  independent  regulatory  com- 
missions or  boards:  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  the  Board  of 
Governors  of  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission, the  Federal  Communications  Commission,  the  Federal  Power 
Commission,  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  the  National 
Labor  Relations  Board,  the  United  States  Maritime  Commission,  and  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  These  bodies  in  the  aggregate  have  vast  powers 
over  transportation  by  rail,  bus,  pipeline,  ocean,  and  air;  communication 
by  telephone,  telegraph,  and  radio;  the  "rules  of  the  game"  by  which  trade 
and  commerce  are  kept  fair  and  competitive;  the  supply  of  electric  power 
across  state  lines  at  reasonable  rates;  the  supply  of  money  and  credit,  the 
issuance  of  stocks  and  bonds,  and  the  operations  of  stock  exchanges;  and  the 
maintenance  of  collective  bargaining  unfettered  by  unfair  practices  on  the 
part  of  employers. 

These  boards  and  commissions  have  five  members  each,  with  the  excep- 
tions of  the  Federal  Reserve  System  and  the  Federal  Communications  Com- 
mission, each  of  which  has  seven  members,  and  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  with  the  unwieldy  number  of  eleven.  Through  staggered 
terms  of  five,  six,  or  seven  years—excepting  the  Board  of  Governors  of  the 
Federal  Reserve  System,  whose  members  serve  for  14  years — and  bipartisan 
membership — not  required  for  this  board  or  the  National  Labor  Relations 
Board — these  establishments  are  intended  to  be  independent  of  any  partic- 
ular chief  executive.  Although  the  President  may  remove  members  of 


222  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

most  of  them  only  for  inefficiency,  neglect  of  duty,  or  malfeasance  in  office, 
he  presumably  has  a  free  hand  on  removals  of  members  of  the  Pfcderal 
Power  Commission,  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  and  Federal  Com- 
munications Commission,  for  the  statutes  set  up  no  bars  to  his  freedom  of 
action  in  these  cases.  In  most  instances  the  President  designates  the  commis- 
sion chairman.  However,  in  the  important  cases  of  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  Federal  Trade  Commission,  and  Federal  Power  Commission 
the  membership  itself  selects  one  of  its  number  as  chairman.13 

It  is  important  to  note  that  regular  executive  departments  exercise  regu- 
latory powers  of  a  character  not  unlike  that  entrusted  to  the  independent 
commissions.  As  Professor  Robert  E.  Cushman  points  out,  "Congress  has 
followed  no  consistent  principle  in  assigning  regulatory  functions  to  inde- 
pendent agencies  rather  than  to  other  units  in  the  national  government. 
There  seems  to  be  nothing  about  the  regulatory  job  which  makes  it  impera- 
tive that  it  be  handled  by  the  same  kind  of  administrative  body."14  The 
Department  of  Agriculture  with  its  regulation  of  packers  and  stockyards 
as  well  as  commodity  exchanges,  and  in  all  some  forty  regulatory  statutes,  is 
an  outstanding  example  in  this  respect.  The  Departments  of  Commerce, 
Interior,  Labor,  and  the  Federal  Security  Agency  with  its  Food  and  Drug 
Administration  also  control  important  economic  activities.15 

During  World  War  II,  vast  regulatory  authority  was  entrusted  to  single- 
headed  agencies  such  as  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  War  Production 
Board,  War  Manpower  Commission,  Petroleum  Administration  for  War, 
Solid  Fuels  Administration,  War  Food  Administration,  and  Office  of 
Defense  Transportation.  It  may  be  added  that  in  performance,  both  the 
independent  commissions  and  the  single-headed  agencies  have  shown  suc- 
cesses and  failures. 

Clientele  Departments  and  Directive  Power.  Among  the  single-headed 
departments,  two  problems  have  been  paramount.  One  has  been  the  special- 
interest  taint  of  the  three  departments  that  would  be  the  most  likely 
single-headed  agencies  for  exercise  of  regulatory  powers:  the  Department 
of  Commerce,  the  businessman's  friend;  the  Department  of  Labor,  the 

13  Sec  Cushman,  Robert  E.,  The  Independent  Regulatory  Commissions,  p.  760  ff.,  New 
York:  Oxford  University  Press,  1941. 

Ulbid.,?.  10. 

15  The  Brookings  Institution  has  suggested  that  the  executive  departments  regulate  and 
control  business  through  an  exercise  of  what  is  virtually  the  "police  power,"  in  the  interests  of 
public  health,  safety,  and  the  prevention  of  fraud.  Here  the  only  factors  involved  arc  a  fixed 
rule  of  law,  a  charge  that  the  law  has  been  broken,  and  a  decision.  The  work  of  independent 
commissions,  on  the  other  hand,  is  distinguishable  because  it  involves  questions  of  public 
policy  on  large  economic  problems,  questions  of  complicated  economic  relationships,  and  prob- 
lems of  public  management.  For  this  point,  see  Senate  Select  Committee  to  Investigate 
the  Executive  Agencies  of  the  Government,  Report  No.  10  of  the  Brookings  Institution, 
Government  Activities  in  the  Regulation  of  Private  Business  Enterprise t  p.  61  ff.,  75th  Cong., 
1st  Sess.,  1937.  See  also  Benson,  George  C.  S.,  "Administrative  Regulation  within  Federal 
Departments,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1942,  Vol. 
221,  pp.  64-71. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  223 

worker's— especially  the  union's— friend;  and  the  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture, the  farmer's  friend.  Thus  a  problem  arises  whenever,  for  example, 
there  is  need  for  regulation  of  both  employers  and  workers  to  assure  col- 
lective bargaining,  prevent  unfair  labor  practices,  facilitate  the  settlement  of 
labor  disputes,  or  control  wages  and  hours.  Should  such  functions  be  as- 
signed to  the  Department  of  Labor,  or  would  that  interfere — or,  what  is 
equally  important,  give  grounds  for  suspicion  of  interference — with  fair 
treatment  of  the  employers'  interests? 

The  second  problem  about  single-headed  departments  has  been  the  ex- 
tent to  which  particular  kinds  of  regulatory  work  may  be  slighted  because 
of  the  influence  of  the  department  head  or  the  President.  The  Justice 
Department,  for  instance,  having  limited  funds  and  staff  like  any  other 
agency,  must  choose  where  it  wishes  to  concentrate  these  resources.  Some- 
times, especially  under  a  conservative  administration,  prosecutions  for  viola- 
tion of  antitrust  laws  may  be  relatively  infrequent.  Under  a  different  kind 
of  administration,  and  without  any  change  in  the  law,  the  Justice  Department 
may  launch  a  full-scale  crusade  against  monopolies.  One  of  the  principal 
justifications  for  the  independent  commissions  is  the  argument  that,  because 
of  their  staggered-term  arrangement  and  relative  freedom  from  execu- 
tive domination,  they  have  greater  continuity  of  policy  than  executive 
departments. 

Struggle  for  Control  Over  Independent  Commissions.  In  the  federal 
government  there  has  been  a  continuing  struggle  for  power  over  the  in- 
dependent commissions  and  boards.  The  protagonists  have  been  the 
President,  Congress,  the  courts,  the  regulated  interests,  and  the  regulatory 
agencies  themselves.  Congress  is  most  powerful  when  a  commission  is 
being  created  or  when  bills  are  before  Congress  for  increasing  or  decreasing 
the  responsibilities  of  particular  commissions.  Congress  may  see  a  need 
under  various  conditions  for  assigning  functions  to  an  independent  com- 
mission having  theoretically  closer  ties  to  the  legislature  than  to  the  Presi- 
dent. Such  conditions  are  given  when:  (a)  Congress  wants  to  set  up  a 
function  on  an  experimental  basis,  with  the  intention  of  passing  a  more 
precisely  worded  statute  after  the  commission  has  felt  its  way  into  the  prob- 
lem and  developed  the  experience  out  of  which  such  a  statute  can  be 
drafted;  (b)  Congress  intends  to  organize  a  function  that  is  largely 
investigational  and  designed  to  lead  to  recommendations  for  legislation 
remedying  the  economic  maladjustments  the  agency  uncovers — much  as  a 
legislative  investigating  committee  might  work;  (c)  Congress  is  defining 
a  function  so  vaguely  and  mixing  various  kinds  of  responsibilities  in  such 
a  way  that  the  agency  will  exercise  powers  of  legislative  and  judicial  char- 
acter as  well  as  of  an  executive  character;  it  is,  therefore  concluded  that 
under  the  doctrine  of  the  separation  of  powers,  the  function  should  not  be 
vested  in  any  of  the  three  branches  of  the  government;  (d)  Congress  is 
disinclined  to  enhance  the  power  of  the  executive  branch  simply  because 


224  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

this  detracts  from  the  prestige  and  strength  of  Congress;  (e)  Congress  is 
distrustful  of  the  particular  President  or  department  heads  in  office  because 
the  administration  is  guided  by  a  political  party,  faction,  or  philosophy 
different  from  that  of  Congress;  (f)  Congress  cannot  find  an  executive 
department  in  which  the  new  function  would  readily  fit;  and  (g)  Congress 
is  under  considerable  pressure  to  afford  representation  in  the  administra- 
tion of  a  regulatory  statute  to  more  than  one  region,  industry,  or  party. 

On  occasion,  when  Congress  and  the  executive  branch  are  under  the 
same  political  control,  they  may  jointly  advocate  creating  an  independent 
commission  to  handle  a  new  and  important  regulatory  power.  The  reason 
might  simply  be  that  under  such  an  arrangement  the  President  can  name 
all  the  members  of  the  new  commission.  Because  of  the  long,  though 
staggered  terms  of  commissioners,  he  can  thus  perpetuate  his  party's  control 
of  the  particular  function  into  and  possibly  through  the  next  presidential 
term.  *- 

The  President  is,  of  course,  the  protagonist  most  frustrated  by  his  lack 
of  control  over  the  execution  of  some  of  the  most  important  statutes  that 
Congress  ever  passed.  Every  president  for  about  the  past  forty  years  has 
sought  to  control  one  or  more  of  the  independent  commissions.10  By  his 
appointments  and  removals;  his  close  relations  with  the  chairmen  of  some 
of  the  commissions;  his  ability  to  mobilize  public  opinion;  his  budgeting 
authority;  and  much  of  the  time  his  standing  with  Congress— by  all  these 
means  the  President,  whoever  he  may  be,  has  been  able  repeatedly  either 
to  influence  commissions  directly  or  to  put  them  on  the  defensive  in  a 
public  battle  in  which  he  has  certain  advantages.  Nevertheless,  the  com- 
missions retain  imposing  powers  of  resistance  to  presidential  direction. 

Humphrey  Case.  The  most  conspicuous  instance  of  a  presidential  at- 
tempt to  control  an  important  commission  resulted  in  judicial  support 
for  the  congressional  doctrine  of  independence  of  regulatory  commissions. 
The  Federal  Trade  Commission,  created  in  1914  under  the  Wilson  Ad- 
ministration, had  been  given  important  powers  to  attack  unfair  methods  of 
competition  and  unlawful  trade  practices  and  to  investigate  business  mis- 
conduct. Before  it  was  four  years  old  this  commission  had  shown  that  it 
interpreted  its  mandate  literally,  and  intended  to  carry  it  out  in  a  vigorous 
manner.  Its  attitude,  particularly  evidenced  by  the  commission's  blistering 
attack  on  the  monopolistic  practices  of  the  meat-packing  industry,  aroused 
the  bitter  resentment  of  much  of  the  business  world.17  It  is  not  surprising 
that  under  the  more  conservative  administrations  of  Presidents  Harding, 

16  Cushman,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  13,  p.  681  ff. 

17  As  a  result  of  the  packing  industry's  hostility  to  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  adminis- 
tration of  the  Packers  and  Stockyards  Act  of  1921  was  assigned  by  Congress  to  the  Secretary  of 
Agriculture,  an  action  that  met  with  the  packing  industry's  favor  because  it  preferred  even  a 
farmer's  and   rancher's  friend   to  the  shrewd,  aggressive  commission  that  had  so  effectively 
exposed  the  practices  of  the  industry. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  225 

Coolidge,  and  Hoover,  a  conscious  effort  was  made  to  put  men  on  the 
Federal  Trade  Commission  who  would  have  less  crusading  zeal  and  who, 
to  a  considerable  extent,  would  exercise  the  commission's  powers  at  sonw 
thing  less  than  their  maximum  extent.18  William  E.  Humphrey,  appointed 
to  the  commission  by  President  Coolidge  in  1925,  dominated  it  between 
1925  and  1933  because  on  most  important  issues  he  could  count  on  the 
votes  of  the  other  two  Republican  commissioners.  Now  collusion  with, 
rather  than  control  of,  trusts  and  monopolies  by  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission was  talked  about  on  the  floor  of  the  House  of  Representatives. 

Shortly  after  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt  was  inaugurated,  he  asked  Com- 
missioner Humphrey  to  resign,  pointing  out  that  Humphrey's  policy  was 
not  in  harmony  with  the  President's  policy  on  the  work  of  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission.  On  the  Commissioner's  refusal,  the  President  re- 
moved him.  Eventually,  the  Humphrey  case  reached  the  Supreme  Court. 
Humphrey's  position  had  rested  on  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  Act, 
which  provided  for  presidential  removal  of  commissioners  "for  inefficiency, 
neglect  of  duty,  or  malfeasance  in  office."  The  chief  executive,  the  argu- 
ment went,  had  violated  this  act  in  removing  Humphrey  not  for  any  of 
these  reasons,  but  for  incompatibility  with  the  President's  views  on  policy 
matters.  The  President,  on  the  other  hand,  relied  on  the  Supreme  Court's 
earlier  decision  and  opinion  in  Myers  v.  United  States,19  in  which  it  was 
held  that  Congress  could  not  constitutionally  restrict  the  power  to  remove 
any  executive  official — in  this  case,  a  postmaster — whom  the  President  had 
appointed  either  alone  or  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  the  Senate.20 

This  was  declared  to  follow  logically  from  a  consideration  of  the  Presi- 
dent's constitutional  possession  of  the  executive  power,  the  power  of  ap- 
pointment, and  the  responsibility  for  taking  care  that  the  laws  be  faithfully 
executed.  And  in  a  dictum  the  majority  of  the  Supreme  Court,  led  by 
Chief  Justice  Taft,  clearly  indicated  that  the  President  has  an  unfettered 
right  under  the  Constitution  to  remove  members  of  quasi-legislative  and 
quasi-judicial  bodies.  However,  in  the  Humphrey  case  the  Supreme  Court 
abandoned  this  dictum.  It  held  instead  that  where  there  is  a  body  exer- 
cising primarily  quasi-legislative  and  quasi-judicial  duties  and  only  inci- 
dentally administrative  or  executive  functions,  such  as  the  Federal  Trade 
Commission,  Congress  may  by  statute  specify  the  causes  for  which  members 
can  be  removed  by  the  President.  In  a  case  like  this,  the  statute  is  binding 

18  It  is  notable  that  in  this  same  period  the  Antitrust  Division  of  the  Department  of 
Justice  showed  none  of  the  enthusiasm  for  its  work  apparent  in  the  Wilson  and  Franklin  D. 
Roosevelt  Administrations,  and  that  the  Supreme  Court,  dominated  by  conservative  justices, 
subjected  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  to  a  rigorous  doctrine  of  judicial  review  of  com- 
mission decisions. 

10 272  U.S.  52  (1926). 

20  The  specific  attempt  to  restrict  the  President's  removal  power  consisted  of  congres- 
sional insistence  that  the  President  obtain  the  consent  of  the  Senate  before  removing  incumbents 
of  certain  executive  offices,  such  as  postmastcrships,  to  which  the  appointment  had  been  by 
the  President  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  the  Senate. 


226  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

on  the  President,  and  he  cannot  remove  for  causes  not  specified  in  the 
statute.  The  Humphrey  case  in  effect  recognized  a  fourth  branch  of  gov- 
ernment, consisting  of  the  independent  commissions.  A  commission  such 
as  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  is  "wholly  disconnected  from  the  execu- 
tive department"  and  is  instead  "an  agency  of  the  legislative  and  judicial 
departments."21 

Experience  in  the  States.  In  the  states  certain  factors  have  given  the 
problem  of  independent  commissions  a  different  setting  than  in  the  federal 
government.21*  Generally  the  legislature  meets  more  infrequently — for  in- 
stance, meeting  only  once  every  two  years.  Thus  it  is  more  difficult  for  the 
apologist  for  independent  commissions  to  argue  that,  though  independent 
of  the  executive,  they  are  given  effective  supervision  and  coordination  by  the 
legislative  branch.  In  the  second  place,  the  general  atmosphere  of  many  state 
governments  is  more  definitely  political,  with  emphasis  on  patronage, 
favoritism,  and  subservience  to  pressure  groups.  In  states  where  this  atmos- 
phere exists — and  it  does  not  exist  in  all — the  departments  responsible  to  the 
governor,  those  responsible  directly  to  the  people,  and  the  independent 
commissions  are  all  affected.  The  agencies  that  come  nearest  to  escaping 
this  atmosphere  are  those  with  professionalized  staffs,  such  as  the  state 
health  department,  the  state  v.  elfare  department,  and  the  state  university. 

Such  service  agencies  with  professional  staffs  are  likely  to  have  a  tradi- 
tion of  both  integrity  and  skill.  They  also  are  backed  by  public  opinion 
or  organized  blocs  of  opinion  in  resistance  to  political  pressures.  In  addi- 
tion, they  have  largely  administrative  rather  than  policy  decisions  to  make. 
In  contrast,  the  heart  of  economic  regulation  is  policy,  and  the  people  are 
ill-served  if  they  have  no  effective  way  to  bring  sanctions  against  the  regu- 
latory commissions,  which  seem  to  float  in  mid-air,  unanswerable  directly 
to  either  of  the  two  political  branches  of  government,  executive  and  legis- 
lative. These  factors  suggest  that  the  people  would  be  better  advised  to  let 
service  agencies,  rather  than  regulatory  bodies,  have  a  high  degree  of 
independence. 

Both  the  degree  of  political  favoritism  running  through  the  conduct  of 
public  affairs  in  some  states  and  a  general  fear  of  strengthening  the  office 
of  governor  when  experience  reveals  the  possibility  that  a  charlatan  may 
be  elected  to  the  post,  result  often  in  a  general  desire  for  the  independence  of 
all  agencies — service  and  regulatory — that  have  important  work  to  do.  While 
this  has  an  appealing  appearance  of  "facing  the  realities,"  it  leaves  the 
governor  with  little  responsibility,  removes  administration  of  a  large  num- 
ber of  governmental  policies  from  effective  public  control,  and  in  some 
cases  causes  a  relative  increase  in  the  control  of  agencies  by  special-interest 
groups.  No  one  is  left  to  call  regulatory  officials  on  the  carpet  promptly 

21  Humphrey's  Executor  v.  United  States,  295  U.  S.  602  (1935). 

22  See    Fesler,    James   W.,    The   Independence    of   State   Regulatory   Agencies,   Chicago: 
Public  Administration  Service,  1942. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  227 

if  they  are  neglecting  the  public  interest.  The  spur  to  action  is  gone,  for 
the  public  itself  is  not  overly  vigilant  about  the  day-to-day  acts  of  regulatory 
agencies.  On  the  other  hand,  the  special  interest  groups  are  likely  to  be 
well  organized  in  their  efforts  to  soften  the  rigors  of  regulation. 

In  the  experience  of  the  states  there  is  no  ready-made  solution  to  the 
problem  of  the  independent  regulatory  bodies.  The  nearest  to  a  solution 
we  can  come  is  to  adopt  the  firm  position  that  policy-making  agencies 
must  be  controlled  by  the  people  through  their  political  instruments,  the 
legislature  and  governor.  Since  the  legislature  meets  infrequently,  and 
is  in  any  event  ill-equipped  to  provide  real  supervision  and  coordination  of 
the  regulatory  agencies,  the  governor  must  be  the  principal  instrument  of 
popular  control.  That  he  is  a  politician,  sometimes  even  a  demagogue  or 
a  tool  of  special  interests,  cannot  be  denied.  Nor  can  it  be  denied  that  regu- 
latory officials  may  have  the  same  defects,  for  politicians  are  often  elected  or 
appointed  to  these  positions.  Certainly,  however,  if  "democratic  govern- 
ment" has  any  meaning  at  all,  it  is  that  policy  must  be  decided  or  con- 
trolled by  the  people.  To  set  the  regulatory  agencies  free  of  this  control 
is  to  insulate  important  areas  of  economic  policy  against  effective  popular 
governance. 

Much  more  important  than  any  mechanical  changes,  though,  would  be 
a  general  improvement  of  the  "tone"  of  state  government.  This  would 
bring  better  men  to  the  legislature  and  to  the  governor's  office.  Such  a 
change  in  turn  would  bring  good  men  to  the  regulatory  agencies. 

4.   THE  PRICE  OF  INDEPENDENCE 

Popular  Illusions.  The  idea  of  independent  regulatory  agencies  has  an 
appeal  to  citizens  who  think  of  politics  as  something  unclean,  of  legislators 
as  controlled  puppets,  and  of  chief  executives  and  their  department  heads  as 
spoilsmen  intent  primarily  on  perpetuating  themselves  in  power.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  same  citizens  are  likely  to  respect  the  courts  and  to  regard 
judges  as  wise  and  well-balanced  men  with  an  unusual  capacity  for  dis- 
covering the  "right"  solution  to  any  problem  of  law,  fact,  or  policy.  How- 
ever, even  a  casual  look  at  legislatures,  courts,  and  executive  departments 
should  reveal  the  extent  to  which  men  and  women  in  the  course  of  their 
public  careers  serve  in  two  and  often  three  of  the  branches  of  government. 
It  should  also  make  evident  the  injustice  of  characterizing  in  blanket  fashion 
as  incompetent  and  corrupt  the  officials  in  any  of  the  three  branches  of 
government. 

The  relevance  of  this  consideration  to  our  topic  lies  in  the  tendency  of 
many  citizens  to  support  independent  commissions  as  a  means  of  bringing 
judge-like  wisdom,  balance,  and  insight  into  the  process  of  regulation  of 
business  and  industry.  Such  an  approach  ignores  two  basic  facts.  One 
is  that  those  appointed  or  elected  to  the  independent  commissions  are  often 
the  same  men  who  before  or  after  their  term  on  the  commission  have  served 


228  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

or  will  serve  as  state  legislators,  governors,  members  of  Congress,  or  execu- 
tive officials.  Some  may  also  be  defeated  candidates  for  political  office,  or 
men  thought  of  primarily  for  past  or  potential  favors  to  the  political  party. 
The  second  fact  ignored  by  commission  enthusiasts  is  the  very  great  dan- 
ger in  any  doctrine  that  pretends  that  we  can  preserve  democracy  and  still 
vest  economic  powers  in  a  governmental  agency  that  is  not  clearly  subject 
to  officials  who  in  turn  are  responsible  to  the  people.  The  proposition  is 
simply  that  policy  is  the  very  thing  to  be  kept  under  effective  popular  con- 
trol if  democracy  is  to  survive.  And  many  regulatory  commissions  make 
more  important  policies,  by  both  action  and  inaction,  than  do  ordinary 
departments.  Almost  by  definition,  a  regulatory  commission  is  set  up  to 
establish  policies  that  the  legislative  body  has  not  been  able  to  determine 
in  any  specific  way. 

Need  for  Policy  Coordination.  This  emphasis  on  policy  as  the  focal 
problem  of  popular  control  of  governmental  regulation  leads  to  another 
main  consideration.  It  is  the  need  for  coordination  of  the  policies  that  are 
being  adopted  and  executed  by  the  scores  of  agencies — executive  and  inde- 
pendent— in  any  government,  on  the  state  or  federal  level.  Clearly,  the 
citizenry  has  a  right  to  demand  that  someone  prevent  its  government's 
right  hand  from  undoing  what  its  left  hand  has  been  trying  to  do.  The 
very  size  of  federal  and  state  administration  makes  perfect  coordination  im- 
possible. However,  the  existence  of  commissions  with  great  regulatory 
powers  claiming  virtual  independence  of  the  chief  executive  seriously 
handicaps  attempts  to  approximate  even  a  rough-hewn  sort  of  coordination. 

Let  us  suppose  a  railroad  situation  in  which  the  problem  involves  rates, 
a  violation  of  the  antitrust  laws,  a  labor  dispute,  competition  by  river  boats 
and  barges,  an  anti-inflation  policy,  and  a  loan  from  the  Reconstruction 
Finance  Corporation.  The  railroad  would  be  at  the  mercy  of  almost  as 
many  agencies  as  there  are  specific  parts  to  the  problem.  If  the  problem  had 
sufficient  importance  to  rise  to  the  President's  level,  he  could  himself  or 
through  an  aide  get  the  executive  agencies  together  and  insist  upon  a  sen- 
sibly articulated  set  of  policies  for  meeting  the  situation.  The  Interstate 
Commerce  Commission,  however,  with  its  control  over  rates  as  part  of  our 
hypothetical  puzzle,  could  stay  away  from  the  conference.  Or,  if  in  attend- 
ance, it  could  decline  to  "go  along"  with  the  other  agencies  on  a  solution. 

Lethargy  of  Independence.  Problems  of  this  character  are  not  fanciful. 
An  illustration  is  the  President's  inability  to  stir  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission  out  of  apparent  lethargy  on  the  vital  policy  problem  of  south- 
ern and  western  freight  rates.  He  deliberately  appointed  a  southern 
expert  on  the  subject  as  a  commissioner.  He  underlined  the  importance  of 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority  freight-rate  studies  by  special  messages  to  Con- 
gress on  the  subject,  with  a  sidelong  glance  at  the  commission.  And  his 
Attorney  General  sued  the  western  railroads  for  violation  of  the  antitrust 
laws.  All  that  did  not  move  the  mountain.  Finally  the  state  of  Georgia 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  229 

brought  the  issue  to  the  Supreme  Court  on  the  charge  that  the  railroads  had 
conspired  to  discriminate  in  their  rates  against  the  South.  By  implication, 
the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  was  accused  as  an  accessory  to  the 
alleged  crime.  In  May,  1944,  shortly  after  the  Supreme  Court  took  jurisdic- 
tion of  the  case,  the  commission  roused  itself  to  issue  a  decision  favoring 
both  the  South  and  the  West,  but  still  not  meeting  the  full  issue  head-on. 

Here  was  an  instance  where  a  great  policy  issue  fell  within  the  juris- 
diction of  an  independent  commission.  The  President  was  apparently 
powerless  to  prod  the  commission  to  action.  The  Supreme  Court  finally 
assumed  jurisdiction  over  this  policy  issue  on  the  basis  of  an  antitrust  suit 
brought  by  a  state.  Only  then  did  the  commission  announce  a  decision, 
the  timing  of  which  suggested  an  attempt  to  beat  the  Supreme  Court  to  the 
draw. 

Pressure  for  Reform.  Such  intransigence  or  even  the  clashing  of  gov- 
ernment agencies  without  ready  means  of  settling  their  disputes  may  be 
charitably  tolerated  during  periods  when  government  is  relatively  inac- 
tive and  disposed  to  let  business  enterprises  "have  their  head."  However, 
when  government's  function  is  conceived  as  positive  in  character,  as  a 
conscious  guidance  of  economic  forces  to  achieve  maximum  production 
for  wartime  needs  or  full  employment  in  times  of  peace,  the  people  and 
the  business  community  itself  insist  that  there  be  a  consistency  among  gov- 
ernmental policies  and  among  the  actions  of  governmental  agencies  in 
executing  those  policies. 

This  does  not  mean  dictatorship;  far  from  it.  It  does  mean  an  organi- 
zation such  as  any  well-run  business  enterprise  would  insist  on — subordina- 
tion to  a  president  or  general  manager  of  virtually  all  functions  that  the 
board  of  directors  does  not  itself  perform.  The  president-manager  can  then 
be  held  responsible  for  seeing  that  the  gears  of  the  enterprise  mesh  rather 
than  clash.  Only  thus  will  all  parts  of  the  company  pull  together  instead 
of  pulling  in  opposite  directions,  with  the  company  remaining  on  "dead 
center." 

Over  the  long  run  of  the  years  ahead  it  seems  very  doubtful  that  the 
people  will  return  to  a  negative  concept  of  government's  role  in  the  economy. 
It  is  therefore  hardly  conceivable  that  they  will  long  tolerate  an  arrange- 
ment whereby  the  most  important  instruments  for  guidance  of  the  economy 
are  independent  commissions  without  close  ties  linking  them  to  one  another 
and  to  either  the  legislature  or  the  executive. 

Lac\  of  Stimulation.  For  independent  commissions,  whatever  their 
advantages,  the  people  pay  a  dear  price  in  a  number  of  ways.  Many  a 
regulatory  commission  is  notably  lacking  in  the  vigor  essential  to  advancing 
toward  the  goals  the  legislative  and  executive  branches  had  in  mind  in 
adopting  the  basic  statutes.  As  a  recent  federal  board  investigating  the  com- 
mission method  of  regulation  observed,  "A  regulatory  statute  may  be  both 
wise  and  practicable,  and  yet  be  totally  ineffective  for  the  simple  reason 


230  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

that  the  agency  takes  no  decisive  action  under  it.  ...  An  agency,  in  fact, 
possesses  through  this  means  a  not  inconsiderable  power  to  thwart  the  legis- 
lative purpose.  .  .  .  An  inactive  agency  will  not  lack  apologists  in  any 
event;  the  difficulty  is  to  find  persons  or  groups  able  and  in  a  position  to 
apply  a  spur."23 

In  the  states  as  well,  many  a  utility  commission,  workmen's  compensa- 
tion and  industrial  safety  board,  banking  and  insurance  board,  and  profes- 
sional licensing  board  shows  little  evidence  of  a  determined  effort  to  define 
and  achieve  the  public  interest.  Public  utilities  commissions,  for  example, 
most  of  them  created  because  the  people  wanted  forceful  regulation  of  the 
intrenched  railroad  and  electric  power  companies,  have  all  too  generally 
taken  a  negative  attitude  toward  exercise  of  their  power. 

The  causes  of  such  reluctance  to  act  vigorously  on  behalf  of  the  public 
are  several.  The  most  important  are  three:  (a)  general  inertia,  which 
can  be  indulged  when  there  are  no  incentives  to  action  and  when  action  is 
bound  to  make  enemies;  (b)  overemphasis  on  the  judicial  approach,  spring- 
ing in  part  from  the  belief  that  commissions  were  made  independent  so 
that  they  could  have  much  the  same  character  and  procedure  as  courts, 
and  in  part  from  the  insistence  of  courts  that  due  process  of  law  requires 
court-like  procedures  in  regulation;  and  (c)  excessive  exposure  to  the 
views  and  influence  of  the  regulated  interests,  without  compensating  ex- 
posure to  governmental  and  private  views  expressive  of  the  public  interest. 
While  these  features  of  unaggressive  regulation  are  most  common  at  the 
state  level,  they  are  discernible  as  well  in  such  respected  federal  agencies 
as  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,24 

5.  ORGANIZATIONAL  ALTERNATIVES 

To  fit  the  independent  regulatory  commissions  into  the  broad  pattern 
of  American  government,  several  alternatives  have  been  advanced.  These 
alternatives  are:  (a)  to  integrate  the  commissions  into  the  executive  branch 
by  clearly  subordinating  them  to  the  chief  executive;  (b)  to  strengthen 
legislative  control  of  the  commissions;  (c)  to  strengthen  judicial  review  of 
the  activities  of  independent  commissions;  and  (d)  to  segregate  the  legis- 
lative, administrative,  and  judicial  phases  of  each  commission's  work,  so 
that  each  phase  of  work  can  be  appropriately  performed.  The  first  three 
alternatives  assume  that  commissions  should  be  assigned  to  one  of  the  main 
branches  of  government  instead  of  remaining  an  unrecognized  and  headless 
fourth  branch  of  government.  The  last  alternative  assumes  that  since 

23  Board  of  Investigation  and  Research,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  5,  pp.  16-17. 

24  For  example,  proposals  to  give  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  jurisdiction  over 
all  forms  of  transportation,  including  air  transport,  have  been  rejected  on  the  ground  that  the 
commission  is  too  "railroad-minded,"  and  could  not  take  a  broad  enough  view  of  the  public 
interest  in  development  of  competitive  methods  of  transportation.    Congress  did   write  the 
fundamentals  of  a  general  transportation  policy  into  the  Transportation  Act  of  1940,  but  it 
is  an  entirely  different  matter  to  expect  an  effective  application  of  these  fundamentals. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  231 

commissions  perform  a  mixture  of  powers  it  would  be  unsound  to  sub- 
ordinate the  commissions  to  any  one  branch  of  government;  however, 
individual  powers  might  be  so  subordinated  or  at  least  be  exercised  by 
distinct  units  of  each  commission. 

Executive  Control.  Integration  under  the  chief  executive's  firm  con- 
trol would  facilitate  coordination  of  policy  and  administration  both  among 
the  commissions  themselves  and  with  the  executive  agencies.  However,  it 
would  place  the  commissions  in  danger  of  more  frequent  shifts  of  policy 
resulting  in  proportionate  instability  for  the  business  world.  It  would  also 
clearly  associate  the  commissions  with  whatever  standards  of  political 
morality  were  observed  by  the  chief  executive — necessarily  a  political  man. 
Most  important,  it  would  place  quasi-judicial  functions  requiring  impar- 
tiality under  the  influence  of  the  policy-minded  chief  executive. 

To  some  students,  on  the  other  hand,  it  is  a  fundamental  error  to  re- 
gard the  chief  executive  as  a  key  formulator  of  policy,  since  constitutional 
emphasis  is  upon  his  executive  functions — that  is,  the  execution  of  policies 
which  are  laid  down  by  the  policy-formulating  branch  of  government,  the 
legislative  body.  Under  this  view,  the  only  advantage  in  integrating  the 
commissions  under  the  chief  executive  would  be  coordination  of  administra- 
tion; the  disadvantage  would  be  exposure  of  commission  policy  to  execu< 
tive  pressure. 

Legislative  Control.  If  emphasis  is  placed  upon  the  need  for  keeping 
the  regulatory  commissions  from  exercising  a  free  and  unguided  hand  on 
policy  matters,  and  if  the  executive  is  ruled  out  as  a  key  formulator  of 
policy,  the  clear  remedy  is  a  strengthening  of  legislative  oversight  of  the 
work  of  the  commissions.  Many  advocates  of  integration  under  the  chief 
executive  would  warmly  embrace  this  legislative  alternative  if  it  offered 
any  possibility  of  success.  However,  experience  to  date  has  not  revealed 
that  our  legislative  bodies  are  equipped  to  give  the  commissions  the  re- 
quired degree  of  supervision. 

Clearly,  state  legislatures  meeting  for  a  few  months  each  year  or  bi- 
ennium  are  not  organized  for  continuing  superintendence  of  regulatory 
work.  Congress  is  in  a  more  favorable  position.  Nonetheless,  after  the 
most  careful  appraisal  of  past  experience  and  future  prospects  for  congres- 
sional control,  Professor  Cushman  concludes  that  "Congress  is  likely  to 
content  itself  with  doing  nothing  for  the  most  part  in  its  dealings  with  the 
commissions,  and  with  resorting  to  some  form  of  drastic  action  when  some- 
thing approaching  a  scandal  crops  up  in  connection  with  a  commission."26 

Recently  we  have  seen  evidence  of  a  serious  intention  to  strengthen  the 
organization  and  procedure  of  Congress.  Success  of  these  efforts  is  to  be 
hoped  for,  but  it  is  unlikely  that  even  after  such  improvement  Congress 
will  supervise  the  independent  regulatory  commissions  with  any  greater 


2fi  Cushman,  of.  at.  nbovc  in  no^  13,  p  678. 


232  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

effectiveness  than  it  has  shown  in  its  relations  with  executive  agencies 
having  regulatory  functions. 

Judicial  Control.  Increased  judicial  control  of  regulatory  commissions 
would  contribute  little  or  nothing  to  the  coordination  of  policy  and  ad- 
ministration. It  could  both  assure  faithful  observance  of  judicial  pro- 
cedure by  the  commissions  and  subject  their  decisions  to  the  risk  of  being 
overruled  if  they  failed  to  coincide  with  the  legal  and  value  judgments  of 
the  courts.  On  the  procedural  side,  extension  of  judicial  restrictions  would 
mean  a  further  formalization  of  commission  procedure.  On  the  substantive 
side,  more  thorough  judicial  review  would  call  in  each  case  for  independent 
judicial  reappraisal  of  the  facts  upon  which  the  commission  had  based  its 
decision. 

Although  in  some  states  there  is  still  need  for  a  tightening  up  of  regu- 
latory procedures  to  make  sure  that  private  rights  receive  due  consideration, 
in  the  federal  government  the  need  is  much  less  obvious.  While  the  Ameri- 
can Bar  Association  has  pressed  for  severe  legislative  restrictions  on  regu- 
latory methods,  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative 
Procedure  has  looked  in  both  directions  at  once.  On  the  one  hand,  it  has 
urged  a  centrally  appointed  group  of  impartial  hearing  commissioners; 
on  the  other,  it  has  rejected  more  extreme  measures,  such  as  a  uniform 
code  of  regulatory  procedure  and  the  abandonment  of  the  informality  of 
procedure  now  followed  in  the  great  majority  of  cases.  In  1944,  a  report  on 
the  practices  and  procedures  of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  cau- 
tioned that  "the  ways  of  the  courts,  if  emulated  too  faithfully,  can  inhibit  the 
Commission  in  the  effective  performance  of  its  duties.  The  judicial  influ- 
ence is  by  no  means  an  unmixed  blessing."26  There  is  a  measure  of  caution 
in  this  respect  in  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of  1946. 

For  the  courts  to  review  not  only  the  legal  questions  in  a  regulatory 
decision  but  also  the  weight  of  the  evidence  would  reduce  the  prestige  of 
regulatory  bodies.  It  would  supplant  their  presumably  expert  judgment  of 
the  facts  of  a  case  with  the  inexpert  judgment  of  members  of  the  judiciary. 
In  practice  the  doctrines  of  court  review  have  a  certain  flexibility.  This  the 
judges  take  advantage  of  in  order  to  review  more  fully  decisions  of  regu- 
latory bodies  in  which  they  lack  confidence,  while  letting  decisions  of  those 
having  been  found  to  possess  integrity,  expertness,  and  formal  court-like  pro- 
cedures escape  severe  judicial  scrutiny.  Furthermore,  court  attitude  toward 
judicial  review  of  decisions  of  regulatory  agencies  fluctuates  to  some  extent 
with  the  variations  in  dominance  of  the  courts  by  conservative  and  progres- 
sive judges.  The  former  extend  judicial  review  to  both  quasi-legislative  and 

26  Board  of  Investigation  and  Research,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  5,  p.  68.  The  Board  devoted 
a  special  section  to  the  problem  of  reluctance  of  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  personnel 
to  take  official  notice  of  even  noncontroversial  legal  and  economic  facts  not  put  in  the  record 
by  the  parties  to  a  hearing;  it  noted  that  in  some  instances  Commission  personnel  even  hold  it 
improper  to  rely  on  earlier  Commission  decisions  unless  they  arc  introduced  as  evidence  at 
the  hearing — a  view  that  is  contrary  even  to  court  practice. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  233 

administrative  actions.  The  latter  tend  to  contract  the  extent  of  judicial 
review  on  the  grounds  that  the  courts  should  not  substitute  their  judgment 
for  that  of  coordinate  branches  of  government,  save  on  clearly  legal 
questions.27 

Segregation  of  Powers  of  Independent  Commissions.  In  effect,  regu- 
latory commissions  have  lines  of  responsibility  running  to  all  three  branches 
of  government,  as  indeed  have  executive  departments  as  well.  The  commis- 
sions are  responsible  to  the  courts  for  staying  within  their  statutory  powers, 
for  following  the  lead  of  the  courts  in  ruling  on  questions  of  law,  and  for 
applying  a  fair  procedure  in  activities  of  a  judicial  character.  The  commis- 
sions are  responsible  to  the  legislative  body  for  broad  policies — responsibility 
enforced  through  its  power  to  amend  the  basic  statutes  and  to  determine 
how  much  money  each  agency  may  spend.  The  responsibility  of  the  com- 
missions to  the  chief  executive  is  the  vaguest  of  the  three  and  a  matter  of 
considerable  dispute  between  him  and  the  commissions.  In  two  capacities 
the  President  appears  to  need  greater  control — in  administrative  manage- 
ment and  in  policy  coordination.  It  can  be  seen  easily  that  the  independent 
commissions  and  the  executive  departments  are  scarcely  distinguishable  in 
the  matter  of  judicial  and  legislative  lines  of  responsibility.  The  principal 
distinction  is  in  the  clarity  of  executive  supervision  of  executive  departments, 
as  contrasted  with  the  fuzziness  of  the  chief  executive's  relations  to  inde- 
pendent commissions.28 

In  view  of  the  difficulty  of  clearly  placing  independent  commissions 
under  one  of  the  three  branches  of  government,  and  also  because  of  cer- 
tain sound  objections  to  merging  quasi-legislative,  administrative,  and  quasi- 
judicial  activities  even  within  a  commission,  it  has  been  proposed  that  some- 
how the  several  powers  of  each  commission  be  segregated.  The  most  fun- 
damental complaint  is  that  prosecuting  and  judging  should  not  be  in  the 
same  hands.  Yet  a  commission  may  decide  what  the  statute  means,  investi- 
gate and  formally  charge  a  person  with  an  alleged  violation,  and  make 
up  its  mind  whether  the  evidence  presented  by  itself  and  the  charged  per- 
son calls  for  a  decision  that  there  was  or  was  not  a  violation.  Actually,  each 
major  commission  is  as  an  institution  composed  of  hundreds  of  officials 
and  employees.  It  is  therefore  possible  to  argue  either  that  segregation 
should  be  absolute  in  the  sense  that  the  commission  should  not  be  respon- 
sible for  both  prosecuting  and  adjudicative  functions;  or  that  the  usua) 
segregation  of  personnel  into  several  units  within  the  commission  should 
suffice  to  keep  the  prosecutors  distinct  from  those  who  do  the  judging, 
while  at  the  same  time  common  direction  of  both  groups  by  the  commis- 


27  For  an  excellent  brief  review  of  this  general  problem,  see  Pennock,  Roland  J.,  "Judicial 
Control  of  Administrative  Decisions,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social 
Science,  1942,  Vol.  221,  pp.  183-191. 

28  See  Cushman,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  13,  p.  697  ff. 


234  INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS 

sion  would  provide  a  reasonably  consistent  pattern  of  regulation.29 
In  addition  to  the  attempt  to  ensure  impartiality  in  adjudication  by 
commissions,  there  is  another  motive  for  segregation.  This  is  the  desire 
clearly  to  subordinate  to  the  chief  executive's  control  at  least  part  of  the 
work  now  done  by  the  independent  commissions.  Of  course,  the  primary 
argument  against  executive  control  of  the  commissions  is  that  such  control 
might  destroy  impartiality  in  the  performance  of  judicial  functions.  The 
advocates  of  executive  control  therefore  have  hit  upon  the  expedient  of 
setting  up,  for  each  area  now  regulated  by  commissions,  one  body  to  hear 
and  decide  impartially  disputes  of  a  judicial  character,  and  another  to  per- 
form all  responsibilities  of  a  policy-formulating  and  administrative  charac- 
ter— including  the  prosecution  function — now  vested  in  the  commissions. 
This  proposal  gained  particular  prominence  when  advanced  by  the  Presi- 
dent's Committee  on  Administrative  Management  in  1937. 

Proposals  of  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management. 
The  President's  Committee  suggested  experimentation  with  a  segregation 
along  specific  lines.  Each  commission  would  retain  its  judicial  functions 
under  the  present  guarantees  of  independence.  For  purely  administrative 
purposes,  however,  it  would  be  attached  to  one  of  the  executive  departments. 
All  of  its  functions  not  of  a  judicial  character  would  be  placed  under  the 
control  of  the  department  head.  The  arrangement  would  safeguard  impar- 
tiality in  the  exercise  of  functions  of  a  judicial  nature.  At  the  same  time, 
it  would  bring  under  executive  control  those  policy-formulating  functions 
and  management  functions  that  properly  fall  within  the  President's  area 
of  responsibility.  Moreover,  by  placing  the  prosecuting  function  under 
executive  control,  it  would  be  separated  clearly  from  the  judicial  function.30 
This  solution  has  not  appealed  to  Congress31  nor  to  the  commissions 
themselves.  The  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Proce- 
dure opposed  such  complete  segregation  on  three  grounds.  One  was  that 
the  consequence  of  multiplication  of  governmental  units  in  identical  fields 
was  objectionable.  The  second  was  that  two  agency  units  in  the  same  field 
would  lead  to  friction,  inconsistency  of  action,  and  a  breakdown  of  respon- 
sibility. The  third  asserted  that  since  such  biases  as  do  exist  on  the  part 
of  regulatory  agencies  "are  mainly  the  product  of  many  factors  of  mind 
and  experience,  and  have  comparatively  little  relation  to  the  administrative 
machinery,"  complete  severance  of  the  judicial  phases  of  regulatory  work 

29  On  this  issue  of  total  vs.  internal  segregation,  see  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  on 
Administrative  Procedure,  op.  at.  above  note  4,  pp.  55-60,  and  203-209. 

80  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Studies,  pp. 
39-42,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937. 

81  In  delegating  to  the  President  authority  to  reorganize  the  executive  branch,  Congress 
in  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  specifically  excepted  the  independent  commissions  from  his 
authority.    The  Reorganization  Act  of  1945  generally  followed  this  precedent. 


INDEPENDENT  REGULATORY  ESTABLISHMENTS  235 

from  its  other  phases  would  not  be  warranted.82  Consequently  the  Attorney 
General's  Committee  recommended  internal  segregation  among  each  com- 
mission's personnel  to  keep  distinct  the  judicial  activity  from  the  prosecuting, 
policy-formulating,  and  administrative  work,  primarily  through  centrally 
appointed  hearing  officers  to  perform  most  of  the  judicial  tasks.  This  is 
the  general  line  taken  by  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of  1946. 

Arrangements  like  these  fail,  of  course,  to  give  the  chief  executive  the  de- 
sired control  over  nonjudicial  activities  of  the  commissions.  Moreover,  in  the 
field  of  public  utilities  there  has  been  a  general  feeling  that  legislative,  execu- 
tive, and  judicial  functions  of  each  commission  "are  so  intertwined  .  .  .  that 
attempts  to  separate  and  segregate  them  will  be  in  all  probability  considerably 
more  destructive  than  constructive."33  At  the  state  level  the  additional 
point  is  made  that  many  state  regulatory  commissions  have  such  small  staffs 
— sometimes  less  than  five  or  ten  employees — that  segregation  is  beyond 
practical  consideration. 

It  is  not  likely  that  any  mass  reorganization  of  federal  and  state  regu- 
latory commissions  will  occur  in  the  near  future.  However,  though  there 
is  disagreement  on  the  remedy,  it  is  an  important  advance  if  the  commis- 
sions have  come  under  sufficiently  close  examination  for  citizens  to  recognize 
several  fundamental  factors.  First,  the  quality  of  men  and  women  appointed 
to  the  commissions  is  more  important  than  the  details  of  organization. 
Second,  judicial  work  should  be  carried  on  in  an  impartial  manner,  free 
of  the  bias  characteristic  of  the  prosecution  function.  Third,  coordination 
of  policy  formulation  and  administrative  management  among  government 
agencies  is  essential,  especially  during  periods  when  government  plays  a 
positive  role  in  the  economy.  The  chief  executive  appears  to  be  the  only 
responsible  and  effective  focus  for  such  coordination.  And  fourth,  independ- 
ent commissions  should  be  subject  to  the  same  control  by  the  legislative 
and  judicial  branches  that  applies  to  all  other  regulatory  and  service  agencies 
of  government. 

^Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4, 
pp.  55-60.  Three  members  of  the  committee  argued  that  internal  segregation  was  not  suffi- 
cient. ,md  in  effect  endorsed  the  President's  Committee's  proposal.  Ibid.,  pp.  203-209. 

83  Board  of  Investigation  and  Research,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  5,  124  ff.,  referring 
specifically  to  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission.  See  also  National  Association  of  Railroad 
and  Utilities  Commissioners,  Report  of  the  Committee  on  Progress  in  Public  Utility  Regulation, 
1938. 


CHAPTER 


Government  Corporations 

1.  CENTRAL  CONTROLS  AND  MANAGERIAL  FREEDOM 

Direction  by  the  Chief  Executive.  A  persistent,  if  not  the  predominant, 
problem  in  the  design  of  governmental  structure  is  the  determination  of  the 
relationship  of  the  agencies  of  administration  to  the  organs  of  popular  con- 
trol—the elected  chief  executives  and  legislatures.  The  general  trend  in 
recent  decades  has  been  to  restrict  the  independence  of  administrative  de- 
partments by  subjecting  them  to  the  direction  of  the  chief  executive.  How- 
ever, for  the  functions  performed  by  independent  regulatory  boards  and 
commissions  the  achievement  of  public  purpose  has  been  thought  to  require 
immunity  from  his  control.  The  government  corporation,  in  its  status  in  the 
general  institutional  framework,  represents  still  another  type  of  organiza- 
tion. While  it  is  usually  subject  to  much  more  control  by  the  chief  execu- 
tive and  the  legislature  over  its  general  policy  than  the  independent  com- 
mission, it  enjoys  far  greater  freedom  than  the  ordinary  department  in  the 
choice  of  means  to  achieve  its  objectives. 

In  the  process  of  making  administrative  agencies  accountable  to  the 
chief  executive,  ordinary  departments  have  come  to  be  hedged  about  by 
many  limitations  on  their  freedom  of  action.  Some  of  these  limitations 
on  departmental  autonomy  concern  the  substance  of  what  is  being  done. 
The  chief  executive  wants  to  move  in  one  direction  rather  than  another. 
He  desires  to  wait  for  a  more  propitious  time  before  a  department  inaugu- 
rates a  program.  He  prefers  this  program  emphasis  or  that.  Such  controls 
of  policy  are  essential  to  direction.  They  are  the  means  by  which  the  chief 
executive  fulfills  his  broad  political  responsibility. 

Overhead  Control  of  Departmental  Methods.  The  process  of  administra- 
tive consolidation  has  brought  still  another  type  of  overhead  control,  which 
is  directed  primarily  toward  the  means  or  methods  of  achieving  substantive 
objectives.  The  department  is  not  only  told  by  higher  authority  what  to  do, 
but  it  is  also  bound  by  more  or  less  detailed  instructions  on  how  to  do  the 
job.  Budget,  personnel,  accounting,  and  legal  officials  on  the  government- 

236 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  237 

wide  level  make  it  their  business  to  see  that  these  instructions  are  formu- 
lated and  followed. 

Integration  of  the  administrative  structure  makes  possible  more  detailed 
and  more  effective  control  by  the  legislature.  In  the  federal  government,  for 
instance,  a  well-prepared  executive  budget  which  presents  information  on 
which  Congress  can  act  is  a  foundation  for  congressional  control.  An  effec- 
tive central  personnel  agency  strengthens  Congress.  For  example,  Congress 
can  fix  salary  scales  and  the  Civil  Service  Commission  will  see  that  they 
are  followed.  The  Comptroller  General,  legally  an  agent  of  Congress,  will 
see  that  legislation  prescribing  the  manner  of  expenditure  of  funds  is 
carried  out  to  the  letter. 

Control  Machinery  in  Action.  The  thoroughness  with  which  legislative 
enactments  can  be  applied  throughout  the  vast  administrative  structure  is 
marvelous  and  awesome.  In  a  more  primitive  administrative  era  the  rule 
books  might  be  filled  with  regulations,  but  they  would  hamper  no  one  as 
long  as  they  could  be  ignored  or  not  as  the  official  saw  fit.  Modern  admin- 
istrative techniques  alter  the  situation  If  Congress  should  abruptly  decide 
that,  beginning  with  the  next  fiscal  year,  no  red-haired  person  was  to  be 
employed  in  the  federal  service,  a  complex  and  far-flung  administrative 
process  would  be  set  in  motion. 

The  Civil  Service  Commission  would  assemble  the  experts  to  advise  it 
in  the  promulgation  of  regulations  defining  "red"  hair.  It  would  exclude 
all  people  within  the  definition  from  its  future  examinations.  It  would 
lay  down  rules  for  the  departments.  To  make  certain  that  the  act  of  Con- 
gress was  carried  out,  it  might  prescribe  that  no  color-blind  person  could 
be  a  personnel  officer.  The  Bureau  of  the  Budget  would  inquire  of  the 
departments  what  steps  were  being  taken  to  avoid  the  expenditure  of  funds 
for  the  prohibited  purpose. 

Each  department  head  would  issue  stern  orders  to  his  personnel  offices. 
Instructions  including  detailed  procedures  for  the  application  of  the  law 
would  flow  to  the  bureau  chiefs,  the  division  chiefs,  and  the  section  chiefs. 
From  Washington,  these  orders  would  go  to  the  federal  field  establishments 
— the  regional,  state,  and  local  offices.  The  regulation  would  find  its  way 
to  outposts  of  the  national  government  in  Alaska,  India,  and  Afghanistan. 
It  would  filter  down  the  administrative  hierarchy  to  the  lowliest  and  most 
remote  office.  The  Comptroller  General  would  require  an  affidavit  from 
each  employee  that  he  or  she  did  not  have  red  hair — probably  accompanied 
by  a  photograph  in  color,  attested  to  be  a  true  likeness  of  the  affiant  by  two 
disinterested  persons!  The  Attorney  General  would  be  asked  to  rule  on  the 
applicability  of  the  law  to  a  completely  bald  person  who  once  had  red  hair; 
and  the  holding  of  the  Attorney  General  might  be  contrary  to  that  of  the 
Comptroller  General. 

The  Federal  Bureau  of  Investigation  would  put  samples  of  hair  through 
the  laboratory  to  detect  evidences  of  dye.  The  courts  would  be  called  upon 


238  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

to  decide  whether  the  law  applied  to  employees  of  state  governments  paid 
in  part  from  federal  grants.  The  Department  of  State,  for  the  good  of  the 
service,  would  seek  from  Congress  an  exception  from  the  law  for  its  locally 
hired  employees  in  Eire.  Congressional  committees  would  be  petitioned  by 
discharged  persons  insisting  that  their  hair  was  titian  and  not  red  as  the 
Comptroller  General  had  held  and  demanding  special  legislation  author- 
izing their  employment. 

The  example  is  fanciful  but  its  essence  could  be  duplicated  a  hundred 
times.  Derived  from  such  controls  over  methods  are-  the  cherished  maxims 
of  our  political  folklore  to  the  etffect  that  government  departments  are  stifled 
by  red  tape,  paralyzed  by  intricate  procedures,  hindered  by  adherence  to 
precedent,  and  bound  by  absurd  rules  and  regulations.  Corollary  beliefs 
are  that  departments  are  ill  fitted  to  undertake  functions  requiring  speedy 
action,  rapid  adaptation  to  new  conditions,  inventiveness,  and  the  exercise 
of  judgment  unfettered  by  petty  rules.  These  notions  abound  most  luxu- 
riantly in  newspaper  editorials,  campaign  speeches,  and  kindred  sources,  and 
in  some  degree  they  possess  an  undeniable  validity. 

Central  Control  and  Departmental  Resourcefulness.  A  government  de- 
partment must  follow  elaborate  procedures  in  estimating  its  future  financial 
needs  and  in  obtaining  appropriations  from  Congress.  It  enjoys  no  assur- 
ance of  continuity  in  its  programs,  for  once  a  year  it  must  seek  funds  from 
a  Congress  that  is  sometimes  friendly  and  sometimes  inexplicably  capri- 
cious. It  must  hire  its  employees  subject  to  intricate  procedures  and  regu- 
lations fixed  by  the  Civil  Service  Commission.  In  spending  money  it  must 
take  care  lest  it  violate  the  voluminous  jurisprudence  on  the  subject  as  inter- 
preted by  the  Comptroller  General.  All  these  controls  arise  to*  meet  demon- 
strated needs.  If  some  such  controls  were  not  in  existence,  they  would  have 
U>  be  invented.  Yet  there  is  a  continuing  necessity  for  adjusting  their  form 
to  reconcile  the  demands  of  administrative  integration  with  the  conditions 
requisite  for  creative  management. 

In  part  because  of  the  controls  applicable  to  the  operations  of  ordinary 
departments  and  in  part  because  of  other  reasons,  the  government  corpora- 
tion is  commonly  regarded  as  a  means  by  which  the  body  politic  can 
conduct  commercial  activities  under  administrative  arrangements  approxi- 
mating those  of  private  enterprise.  In  a  frequently  quoted  passage,  British 
Laborite  Herbert  Morrison  has  argued  for  the  use  of  the  corporation  in  the 
management  of  publicly-owned  commercial  enterprise  because  such  an  un- 
dertaking "should  be  able  with  speed  and  decision  to  adapt  itself  to  the 
changing  needs  of  the  modern  world."  Such  characteristics  are  not  with- 
out merit  in  the  ordinary  department,  but  they  are  indispensable  in  a  com- 
mercial enterprise  if  it  is  to  survive. 

Changing  Role  of  Government  Corporations.  A  "pure"  form  of  gov- 
ernment corporation  would  be  one  in  which  government  owned  all  or  the 
majority  of  the  stock  of  an  incorporated  enterprise.  Government,  like  a 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  239 

private  stockholder,  would  look  to  the  managers  for  the  efficient  conduct 
of  the  enterprise  and  would  measure  performance  by  the  volume  of  divi- 
dends and  the  state  of  the  balance  sheet.  It  would  leave  to  the  officers  of 
the  corporation  the  tasks  of  management:  the  methods  of  personnel  selec- 
tion; the  rules  for  purchasing  supplies;  the  terms  on  which  sales  would  be 
made;  the  disposition  of  revenues  and  profits;  and  so  forth.  For  example, 
if  the  federal  government  should  purchase  fifty-one  per  cent  of  the  stock 
of  the  American  Telephone  &  Telegraph  Company,  it  could  receive  its 
dividends,  observe  the  general  results  of  operation,  and,  if  dissatisfied,  use 
its  majority  stock  control  to  replace  the  management.  In  practice,  however, 
governmental  use  of  the  corporate  device  for  the  conduct  of  pure  commer- 
cial enterprise  is  exceptional.  It  is  used  largely  for  functions  in  the  no 
man's  land  between  ordinary  governmental  functions  and  commercial 
activities.1 

Although  the  federal  government  has  owned  and  operated  corporations 
which  approximated  the  "pure"  type  in  their  autonomy  and  in  their  form, 
government  corporations  have  gradually  lost  most  of  the  characteristics  of 
the  private  corporation  and  have  become  more  and  more  like  ordinary 
administrative  departments.  This  trend  toward  the  assimilation  of  corpora- 
tions into  the  regular  governmental  pattern  moved  a  step  further  with  the 
passage  of  the  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945.  Even  under 
that  act,  corporations  retained  a  degree  of  autonomy  not  uniformly  enjoyed 
by  departments.  The  discussion  which  follows  must  of  necessity  be  in  con- 
siderable measure  an  historical  analysis  indicating  the  process  by  which 
government  corporations  reached  the  stage  of  development  marked  by 
this  federal  statute. 

1  Of  some  importance  is  the  means  of  formation  of  government  corporations.  In  some 
instances  they  are  formed  by  federal  officials  proceeding  under  state  laws  in  the  same  manner 
as  private  incorporators.  Such  action  is,  of  course,  taken  in  pursuance  of  some  sort  of  authori- 
zation by  federal  law.  In  other  instances  government  corporations  are  created  specifically  by 
.icts  of  Congress.  In  a  third  type  of  situation  the  corporation  may  be  formed  by  federal  officials 
— acting  as  "incorporators" — under  general  or  specific  authorization  by  Congress.  In  a  few 
instances  private  corporations  have  become  "government"  corporations  by  public  acquisition  of 
their  capital  stock. 

As  to  the  federal  government,  there  has  been  considerable  discussion  looking  toward  the 
enactment  of  a  statute  providing  a  uniform  method  for  the  formation  of  corporations  together 
with  a  degree  of  uniformity  of  corporate  rights  and  responsibilities.  The  lack  of  such  a  statute 
has  made  difficult  congressional  control  over  the  creation  of  corporations;  some  existing  cor- 
porations were  originally  pegged  on  statutory  clauses  which  doubdess  were  enacted  without 
expectation  that  they  would  be  so  used.  Past  practice  in  chartering  corporations  also  created 
some  difficulty  in  controlling  the  scope  of  corporate  activity.  The  Government  Corporation 
Control  Act  (Public  Law  No.  248,  79th  Cong.,  approved  Dec.  6,  1945)  prohibits  the  organiza- 
tion or  acquisition  of  any  government  corporation  "for  the  purpose  of  acting  as  an  agency  or 
instrumentality  of  the  United  States,  except  by  Act  of  Congress  or  pursuant  to  an  Act  of 
Congress  specifically  authorizing  such  action."  The  same  act  requires  the  liquidation  by  June 
30,  1948,  of  all  wholly  government-owned  corporations  formed  under  laws  of  the  states  or 
the  District  of  Columbia,  unless  reincorporated  by  act  of  Congress  prior  to  that  date. 


240  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

2.  THE  DEVELOPMENT  OF  THE  CORPORATE  SYSTEM  IN  GOVERNMENT 

Variety  of  Government  Corporations.  Rationalizations  for  the  use  of  the 
government  corporation  have  been  erected  on  the  assumption  that  it  should 
be  resorted  to  primarily  for  the  administration  of  self-sustaining  commercial 
undertakings.  Only  when  such  a  function  is  performed  can  there  be  a 
source  of  funds  for  operation  other  than  appropriations.  Only  with  such 
non-tax  revenues  is  it  feasible  for  long  to  grant  autonomy  in  internal  man- 
agement of  the  affairs  of  the  undertaking,  since  nearly  all  the  controls 
applicable  to  the  ordinary  department  stem  from  the  fact  of  expenditure 
from  the  public  treasury.  However,  in  many  instances  government  corpora- 
tions have  been  charged  with  functions  of  a  noncommercial  or  quasi- 
commercial  character  more  akin  to  those  of  an  old-line  department  than  to 
those  of  a  business  enterprise. 

Consequently,  in  the  United  States  government  corporations  are  of 
"somewhat  limited  value"  in  illustrating  their  use  as  a  means  of  managing 
publicly  owned  commercial  enterprises.2  Partly  because  of  the  nature  of 
the  functions  imposed  upon  them,  government  corporations  have  also  ac- 
quired, through  congressional  and  executive  action,  a  great  diversity  of 
form.  It  is  thus  misleading  to  speak  of  "the"  government  corporation.  No 
uniformity  of  powers  or  of  form  is  apparent;  about  all  that  government 
corporations  have  in  common  is  the  name.  This  diversification  has  been 
carried  so  far  that  a  leading  student  of  the  subject  has  concluded  that  "the 
government  corporation  as  a  concept — as  a  definite  and  specialized  form  of 
administrative  organization — is  rapidly  ceasing  to  exist."3  Nevertheless, 
the  agencies  that  masquerade  under  the  title  of  corporation  differ  in  many 
respects  from  the  ordinary  departments. 

The  nature  and  form  of  individual  corporations  have  been  determined 
by  a  variety  of  factors.  The  ideas  prevailing  at  the  time  are  reflected  in 
corporations  formed  in  different  periods.  The  kind  of  function  performed 
has  been  of  some  importance,  for  those  corporations  that  conduct  more 
truly  commercial  activities  seem  to  have  maintained  a  higher  degree  of 
corporate  autonomy.  The  political  strength  of  their  constituencies  has  a 
bearing  on  the  form  of  many  corporations.  Thus,  by  virtue  of  its  popular 
support,  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  has  been  able  to  resist  proposals 
to  convert  it  into  something  more  nearly  approximating  a  regular  depart- 
ment. A  considerable  number  of  corporations,  usually  some  time  after 
their  establishment,  have  felt  the  pressure  of  Congress  to  force  them  into 
the  mold  of  an  ordinary  department. 

2  Thurston,  John,  Government  Proprietary  Corporations  in  the  English-Speaking  Countries, 
p.  6,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1937. 

3Pritchctt,  C.  H.,  "The  Paradox  of  the  Government  Corporation,"  Public  Administration 
Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  381. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  24l 

Government  Corporations  as  Products  of  Emergencies.  Most  govern- 
ment corporations  have  been  products  of  emergency  conditions,  although 
their  life  does  not  always  end  with  the  emergency  which  gave  them  birth. 
In  war  and  depression  the  federal  government  has  been  compelled  to  under- 
take activities  of  an  extraordinary  character.  Pressure  for  speedy  action 
made  the  corporate  form  with  its  freedom  from  cumbersome  procedures 
attractive.  However,  the  oldest  existing  government  corporation—the  Pan- 
ama Railroad  Company — came  into  government  ownership  under  different 
circumstances.  In  1903,  the  United  States  acquired  the  French  interest  in 
the  canal  and  in  the  railroad  company  which  had  been  incorporated  under 
the  laws  of  New  York  in  1849.  The  federal  government  has  continued  to 
operate  the  company  under  its  original  charter.  In  addition  to  tht  railroad, 
the  company  operates  hotels,  commissaries,  steamships,  dairies,  laundries,  and 
other  enterprises.  It  is  administered  under  the  War  Department  in  close 
affiliation  with  the  Canal  Zone.  Partially  because  of  its  monopolistic  posi- 
tion, it  has  been  a  profitable  enterprise.4  The  Inland  Waterways  Corpora- 
tion, formed  in  1924,  is  another  instance  in  which  emergency  conditions  did 
not  govern  the  choice  of  administrative  form.5  The  corporate  arrangement 
was  deliberately  chosen  because  of  its  advantages  over  the  then  existing 
departmental  structure.  The  corporation  operates  the  Federal  Barge  Lines 
which  in  1943  had  a  gross  operating  revenue  of  $8.3  millions. 

With  these  exceptions,  and  the  further  exception  of  the  Federal  Land 
Banks  which  were  authorized  in  1916  after  long  inquiry  into  the  problem 
of  agricultural  credit,  the  federal  corporate  system  has  been  a  creature  of 
war  and  depression.  The  first  large-scale  use  of  corporations  occurred  in 
World  War  I,  when  such  bodies  included  the  United  States  Housing  Cor- 
poration, the  United  States  Grain  Corporation,  the  War  Finance  Corpora- 
tion, the  Emergency  Fleet  Corporation,  and  the  United  States  Spruce  Pro- 
duction Corporation.  Experience  gained  at  that  time  brought  a  recogni- 
tion of  the  potentialities  of  the  corporation  and  furnished  precedents  for 
subsequent  action.6 

Great  Depression  and  World  War  II.  The  Great  Depression  was  a 
second  occasion  for  the  creation  of  a  considerable  number  of  corporations. 
The  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  was  formed  in  1932  in  an  attempt 
to  stave  off  economic  disaster  by  loans  to  business — banks,  insurance  com- 

4  See  Dimock,  Marshall  £.,  Government-Operated  Enterprises  in  the  Panama  Canal  Zone, 
Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1934.  Much  of  our  knowledge  of  the  government  corpor- 
ation has  been  made  available  by  Professor  Dimock  through  his  own  writings  and  studies  by  his 
students. 

5  See  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  Developing  America's   Waterways,  Chicago:    University  of 
Chicago  Press,  1935. 

6  See  Van  Dorn.  Harold,  Government-Owned  Corporations,  New  York:  Knopf,  1926. 


242  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

panics,  railroads,  and  other  types  of  enterprise.7  The  functions  of  the  cor- 
poration were  broadened  after  its  establishment,  and  through  the  spawning 
of  subsidiaries  it  eventually  became  a  huge  holding  company.  The  Home 
Owners  Loan  Corporation  was  another  type  of  emergency  credit  agency. 
Created  in  1933,  it  had  the  function  of  refinancing  home  mortgages  threat- 
ened with  foreclosure.  By  the  end  of  its  lending  operations  in  1936  it  had 
refinanced  over  $3  billions  in  home  mortgages.  It  continues  to  exist,  ful- 
filling the  functions  of  collecting  its  mortgages  and  managing  the  prop- 
erties acquired  in  its  operations.  Another  variety  of  emergency  corporation 
was  the  Federal  Surplus  Commodities  Corporation,  which  was  chartered  in 
1933  for  the  purpose  of  buying  agricultural  surpluses  and  of  distributing 
them  to  relief  agencies — hardly  a  profit-making  enterprise  but  one  involving 
large  purchasing  operations  which  could  be  carried  on  more  handily  under 
corporate  arrangements. 

The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  though  a  permanent  institution,  was 
also  of  depression  origin.  It  was  created  in  1933  with  functions  of  a  mixed 
governmental  and  commercial  nature,  and  it  is  notable  both  for  its  cor- 
porate form  and  as  an  experiment  in  multiple-purpose  regional  administra- 
tion. The  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation,  another  permanent 
agency  of  emergency  origin,  was  charged  with  the  insurance  of  bank  depos- 
its of  less  than  $5,000,  a  risk  too  great  to  be  carried  by  private  enterprise 
and  difficult  of  assumption  save  through  compulsory  coverage  on  a  large 
scale.  The  Federal  Savings  and  Loan  Insurance  Corporation  (1934)  had  a 
similar  objective  in  the  protection  of  investments  in  savings  and  loan  insti- 
tutions. Federal  Prison  Industries,  Inc.  (1934)  involved  the  incorporation  of 
an  existing  activity,  a  move  perhaps  influenced  by  the  frequent  resort  to  use 
of  the  corporate  device  in  other  activities  at  the  time.  The  corporation  sells 
to  government  departments,  which  are  obliged  to  buy  from  it,  and  employs 
workers  who  have  no  alternative  market  for  their  labor.  It  makes  money. 
Other  corporations  created  in  the  early  1930's  included  the  Commodity 
Credit  Corporation  (1933),  the  Federal  Farm  Mortgage  Corporation  (1934), 
the  Mortgage  Corporation  (1935)  under  the  Reconstruction  Finance  Cor- 
poration, and  the  Federal  Home  Loan  Banks  (1932). 

World  War  II  brought  another  spurt  in  corporate  activity  with  the 
creation  of  a  number  of  corporations,  principally  as  subsidiaries  of  the 
Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation,  to  carry  on  war  activities  which  are 
notoriously  of  a  risky  character.  The  Defense  Homes  Corporation  (1940) 

7  See  Senate  Doc.  No.  172,  76th  Cong.,  3d  Sess.,  Pt.  1,  pp.  50-52,  1940.  This  document 
Consists  of  a  report  prepared  by  the  Treasury  Department  in  response  to  a  Senate  request;  it 
contains  detailed  information  on  each  of  the  corporations  in  existence  at  the  time.  For  a 
more  recent  and  much  briefer  description,  see  Joint  Committee  on  Reduction  of  Non-Essential 
Expenditures,  Government  Corporations,  Senate  Doc.  No.  227,  78th  Cong.,  2d  Sess.  A  more 
comprehensive  description  of  each  corporation  is  to  be  found  in  Reference  Manual  of  Govern- 
went  Corporations,  prepared  by  the  General  Accounting  Office  and  printed  as  Senate  Doc.  No. 
*6,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  1945. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  243 

was  organized  to  construct  homes  in  areas  congested  by  defense  activity. 
The  Defense  Plant  Corporation  (1940)  was  created  to  finance  and  construct 
plants  for  war  production;  it  became  the  owner  of  billions  in  plants  and 
machinery.  The  Defense  Supplies  Corporation  (1940)  and  the  Metals 
Reserve  Company  (1940)  were  established  to  buy  and  sell  strategic  and 
critical  materials.  The  Rubber  Development  Corporation  (1940)  was  given 
the  job  of  developing  and  procuring  natural  rubber  abroad,  principally  in 
Latin  America,  while  the  Rubber  Reserve  Company  (1940)  was  formed  to 
construct  synthetic  rubber  plants.  The  United  States  Commercial  Company 
(1942),  another  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  subsidiary,  was  char- 
tered to  engage  chiefly  in  preclusive  buying  abroad— that  is,  buying  critical 
materials  regardless  of  price  to  prevent  their  falling  into  the  hands  of  the 
enemy.8 

In  1945,  several  of  the  defense  subsidiaries  of  the  Reconstruction  Finance 
Corporation  were  merged  with  the  parent  company  and  lost  their  separate 
identity.  Those  affected  by  Public  Law  No.  109,  approved  June  30,  1945, 
were:  Defense  Plant  Corporation,  Metals  Reserve  Company,  Rubber  Reserve 
Company,  Defense  Supplies  Corporation,  and  Disaster  Loan  Corporation. 
The  Coordinator  of  Inter-American  Affairs  formed  several  corporations  to  be 
used  as  instrumentalities  in  the  promotion  of  the  Good  Neighbor  Policy. 
They  were  the  Institute  of  Inter-American  Affairs,  the  Institute  of  Inter- 
American  Transportation,  the  Inter-American  Educational  Foundation,  Inc., 
the  Inter-American  Navigation  Corporation,  and  Prencinradio,  Inc. 

Government  Corporations  in  the  Field  of  Farm  Credit.  The  corporation 
has  been  the  characteristic  administrative  form  in  the  elaborate  governmental 
system  for  farm  credit  which  has  grown  steadily  since  1916.  The  twelve 
Federal  Land  Banks,  organized  in  1917  under  the  Federal  Farm  Loan  Act 
of  1916,  are  mixed  in  ownership,  with  part  of  the  stock  being  owned  by 
the  federal  government  and  part  by  national  farm  loan  associations— that 
is,  borrowers'  cooperatives.  The  Federal  Land  Banks  have  revolutionized 
long-term  farm  mortgage  lending  practices;  their  outstanding  loans  at  the 
end  of  1943  totalled  $13  billions. 

The  credit  system  was  broadened  in  1923  with  the  creation  of  twelve  Fed- 
eral Intermediate  Credit  Banks  which  make  loans  and  discounts  for  lending 
institutions  engaged  in  short-term  financing  of  farm  production;  their  loans 
and  discounts  in  1943  were  about  $1  billion.  The  twelve  Production  Credit 
Corporations,  set  up  in  1933,  organize  and  finance  local  production  credit 
associations  which  in  turn  make  short-term  loans  to  farmers.  In  theory, 
these  local  associations  are  credit  cooperatives  with  some  of  their  capital 
subscribed  by  the  Production  Credit  Corporations.  All  these  financing 

*See  Gordon,  David,  "How  We  Blockaded  Germany,"  Harper's  Magaxine,  December, 
1944,  Vol.  190,  pp.  14-22. 


244  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

institutions  and  certain  others  have  been  under  the  supervision  of  the  Farm 
Credit  Administration. 

Scope  of  Corporate  System.  The  net  effect  of  the  development  of  the 
corporate  system  was  that  by  1944  there  were  in  existence  in  the  neighbor- 
hood of  one  hundred  government  corporations,  the  precise  number  varying 
with  idiosyncracies  in  definition.  In  the  aggregate  the  corporations  in  the 
fiscal  year  of  1944  spent  $58.8  millions  for  administrative  expense  and  $303.3 
millions  for  nonadministrative  expense.  They  used  $8.68  billions  for  the 
purchase  and  improvement  of  property,  principally  war  plants  and  supplies, 
and  loaned  $1.02  billions.  These  same  agencies,  from  their  inception  to  the 
end  of  1944,  had  spent  $18.9  billions  for  the  purchase  and  improvement  of 
property  and  had  loaned  $202  billions.9 

3.  OVERHEAD  CONTROL  OF  CORPORATE  OPERATIONS 

Immunity  from  the  Power  of  the  Purse.  The  ordinary  government 
department  is  subject  to  overhead  controls  applied  by  the  Bureau  of  the 
Budget,  the  Department  of  Justice,  the  Comptroller  General,  and  the  Civil 
Service  Commission.  Through  decades  of  evolution  these  controls  and 
procedures  have  become,  as  David  E.  Lilienthal  has  said,  "stupefying"  in 
their  complexity.10  Although  such  limitations  on  departmental  action  are  by 
no  means  without  utility,  they  often  delay  operation:  they  limit  departments 
in  the  choice  of  means  to  achieve  ends;  they  sometimes  smother  initiative; 
and  too  often  they  become  pointless  ritual.  Long  experience  has  demon- 
strated the  need  for  limits  on  officials  who  spend  other  people's  money. 
However,  in  some  types  of  governmental  undertakings,  reliance  on  the 
traditional  prescriptions  rather  than  on  alternative  methods  of  measuring 
performance  makes  it  difficult  to  accomplish  the  job  assigned  to  an  agency; 

Administratively,  the  most  significant  privilege  enjoyed  by  a  full-fledged 
government  corporation  is  its  freedom  from  the  customary  rules  about 
finance.  These  rules  stem  from  the  great  constitutional  principle  that  no 
money  may  be  paid  from  the  Treasury  except  in  pursuance  of  law.  The 
principle  lays  the  basis  for  control  by  the  executive  and  legislative  branches 
over  the  administrative  agencies.  The  power  of  the  purse  is  used  to  deter- 
mine the  amounts  to  be  spent  for  each  of  the  purposes  of  government.  It 
is  also  used  to  prescribe  in  greater  or  lesser  detail  precisely  how  the  money 
shall  be  spent. 

Another  principle — a  necessary  corollary  of  the  first — is  that  public 
revenues  shall  be  deposited  in  the  Treasury.  Without  adherence  to  this 
maxim,  public  moneys  might  be  spent  directly  from  revenue  without  specific 
appropriation  by  the  legislature.  A  third  fundamental  principle  is  that  of 
annual  appropriations.  Invariable  adherence  to  it  has  not  been  achieved.  A 

9  Treasury  Department,  Bulletin,  pp.  66-68,  Sept.,  1944.  The  figures  are  from  tables  under 
the  heading,  "Certain  Government  Corporations  and  Credit  Agencies." 

10  TVA— Democracy  on  the  March,  p.  168,  New  York:  Harper,  1944. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  245 

few  permanent  appropriations — that  is,  standing  authorizations  for  the  ex- 
penditure of  specified  amounts  each  year — remain  on  the  books.  Yet  annual 
appropriation  is  the  general  practice  in  the  federal  government.  This  is  of 
profound  importance.  It  means  that  the  power  of  the  purse  is  exerted  at 
annual  intervals.  The  burden  of  proof  and  pressure  is  annually  placed  upon 
those  who  desire  money. 

The  government  corporation  furnishes  a  method  of  modifying  these 
principles.  A  subscription  by  government  to  the  capital  stock  of  a  corpora- 
tion or  an  allocation  of  funds  to  the  corporation  removes  the  money  from 
the  Treasury  and  from  annual  appropriation  control.  The  funds  may  be 
utilized  until  exhausted  whether  it  takes  one  year  or  ten.  Earnings  of  the 
corporation,  since  they  may  be  corporate  funds  rather  than  public  revenues, 
need  not  be  covered  into  the  Treasury  but  may  be  retained  in  the  custody 
of  the  corporation.  They  may  then  be  spent  at  the  discretion  of  the  officers 
of  the  corporation,  though  only  within  the  limits  of  corporate  purposes 
fixed  by  the  charter.  If  the  corporation  is  engaged  in  a  self-sustaining  func- 
tion, its  revenues  would  enable  it  to  operate  on  its  own  resources  more  or 
less  indefinitely  without  annual  subjection  to  the  presidential  and  congres- 
sional power  of  the  purse. 

It  is  usually  pointed  out  that  in  the  avoidance  of  customary  regulations 
about  expenditure  a  superior  type  of  control  becomes  possible.  If  a  revenue- 
producing  function  is  involved,  analysis  of  the  financial  operations  by  ordi- 
nary methods  applied  by  private  corporations  will  furnish  a  means  of 
evaluating  performance.  Is  the  enterprise  coming  out  even  or  is  it  yielding 
a  return  on  the  government's  investment?  Thus  the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority  attempts  to  indicate  in  its  financial  reports  the  degree  to  which 
its  power  operations  are  paying  their  way.  This  can  be  contrasted  with  the 
Post  Office  accounting  in  which  a  profit  may  be  claimed  while  no  charges 
are  made  for  capital,  depreciation,  or  other  factors  which  are  weighed  in 
business  accounting. 

Fiscal  freedom  makes  the  measurement  of  performance  feasible.  How- 
ever, probably  of  greater  importance  in  the  case  made  for  corporate 
autonomy  are  certain  characteristics  of  the  appropriation  procedure  for 
ordinary  departments.  It  is  very  difficult  to  forecast  specifically  the  financial 
requirements  of  a  commercial  enterprise.  If  business  is  unexpectedly  good, 
the  increased  revenues  must  be  available  to  meet  the  increased  operating 
charges.  Moreover,  application  of  the  usual  appropriation  procedures  to 
commercial  enterprises  is  made  less  practicable  by  the  length  of  the  appro- 
priation cycle.  An  ordinary  department  must  anticipate  its  financial  needs 
long  in  advance  of  actual  expenditure.  Thus  each  summer  a  department 
must  begin  the  preparation  of  its  expenditure  estimates  to  cover  the  fiscal 
year  that  will  end  on  June  30  two  years  later.  It  must  ordinarily  present 
its  estimates  for  review  by  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  about  September  of 
the  year  preceding  the  beginning  of  the  fiscal  year  covered  by  the  estimates 


246  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

It  will  subsequently  justify  the  estimates  as  approved  by  the  President  to 
congressional  committees,  and  final  action  will  be  taken  by  Congress  shortly 
before  the  beginning  of  the  fiscal  year. 

The  difficulties  of  forecasting  revenues  and  expenditures  of  commercial 
enterprise  are  illustrated  by  an  experience  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Au- 
thority. Estimates  of  power  revenues  and  expenses  of  power  production 
prepared  in  the  summer  of  1939  for  the  fiscal  year  ending  June  30,  1941, 
were:  revenues,  $14.7  millions;  direct  power  expenses,  $5.6  millions.  In 
fact,  however,  revenues  turned  out  to  be  $21  millions  and  expenses  about 
$9  millions.11  Under  ordinary  budget  procedure,  TVA  would  have  had  to 
go  back  to  Congress  for  additional  appropriations  to  meet  the  unforeseen 
conditions.  Under  corporate  practice,  the  increased  revenues  were  avail- 
able without  congressional  action  to  meet  the  increased  expenses. 

Another  example  is  furnished  by  the  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corpo- 
ration. Its  revenues  consist  of  assessments  on  the  deposits  of  insured  banks, 
together  with  the  earnings  of  investments  of  the  capital  and  surplus  of 
the  corporation.  The  losses  paid  to  depositors  in  closed  banks  have  fluctu- 
ated violently  over  the  years.  Deposit  insurance  losses  and  expenses  have 
ranged  from  a  low  of  $1.3  millions  in  1942  to  a  high  of  $14.0  millions  in 
1939.  The  corporation  attempts  to  pay  depositors  as  soon  as  possible  after 
a  bank  is  closed — the  next  day  if  practicable.  Any  attempt  to  estimate 
losses  and  provide  for  them  by  appropriations  would  be  doomed  to  failure 
unless  the  appropriations  were  coupled  with  authority  virtually  approxi- 
mating the  present  range  of  discretion  of  the  corporation. 

Freedom  to  plan  and  make  expenditures  within  the  limits  of  funds 
available  is  important  because  of  the  difficulties  of  forecasting.  Equally 
important  is  the  fact  that  such  freedom  gives  the  corporate  officials  greater 
discretion  in  determining  how  the  corporation  is  to  be  managed.  If  the 
expenditure  program  must  go  through  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  and  the 
Appropriations  Committees  of  Congress,  the  corporate  determinations  of 
how  the  funds  are  best  to  be  expended  will  almost  certainly  be  questioned. 
The  judgment  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  acting  for  the  President,  and 
the  opinion  of  the  congressional  committees  may  be  substituted  for  con- 
clusions of  those  responsible  for  the  management  of  the  corporation.  By 
this  limitation  of  their  discretion,  corporate  managers  assert,  their  power 
ceases  to  be  commensurate  with  their  responsibility  for  the  management 
of  the  affairs  of  the  corporation. 

Restrictions  on  Corporate  Autonomy.  Such  are  the  considerations  urged 
in  support  of  fiscal  autonomy  for  government  corporations.  In  practice, 
corporate  autonomy  in  the  disposition  of  revenues  has  been  sharply  re- 
duced. The  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945  subjected  all 
corporations  wholly  owned  by  the  federal  government  to  a  uniform  type 

11  Finer,  Herman,  The  TVA:  Lessons  for  International  Application,  p.  189,  Montreal: 
International  Labour  Office,  1944. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  24? 

of  budgetary  control,  which  we  shall  describe  shortly.  Even  before  the 
adoption  of  this  law,  successive  actions  by  the  President  and  Congress  had 
narrowed  corporate  autonomy  in  the  determination  of  expenditure  pro- 
grams. These  actions  left  only  the  Inland  Waterways  Corporation,  the 
Panama  Railroad  Company,  and  certain  agricultural  credit  corporations 
of  mixed  ownership  in  full  enjoyment  of  the  power  to  adopt  operating 
programs  for  the  expenditure  of  their  revenues. 

From  its  establishment  in  1924,  the  Inland  Waterways  Corporation  had 
not  had  to  seek  annual  appropriations  for  operating  expenses.  Revenues 
from  the  operation  of  the  Federal  Barge  Line  and  other  sources  were  spent 
for  the  conduct  of  the  business  in  the  discretion  of  the  corporate  manage- 
ment. The  corporation  did  not  have  to  estimate  long  in  advance  how  many 
workers  it  would  need  to  man  its  transport  facilities,  justify  these  estimates 
to  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  and  to  congressional  committees,  and  operate 
within  the  limits  of  a  congressional  appropriation.  Rather,  it  paid  its 
expenses  of  operation  from  its  revenues  after  the  fashion  of  a  private  cor- 
poration. Similarly,  and  for  a  much  longer  period  of  time,  the  Panama 
Railroad  enjoyed  the  privilege  of  managing  its  affairs  within  the  limits 
of  its  resources. 

Prior  to  1945,  the  general  tendency  had  been  toward  greater  control  by 
overhead  executive  agencies  and  by  Congress  over  the  financial  program- 
ming of  corporations.  In  some  instances  this  trend  was  attributable  to 
the  fact  that  the  corporation  did  not  possess  funds,  either  from  its  own 
earnings  or  from  other  sources,  adequate  to  meet  its  needs;  it  thus  had 
to  seek  appropriations  to  finance  its  operations.  In  these  situations  the 
theory  of  corporate  freedom  was  never  completely  applied.  It  was  perhaps 
equally  important  in  the  extension  of  budgetary  and  appropriation  control 
that  central  budget  officials  and  the  Appropriations  Committees  were  on  the 
whole  ill  disposed  toward  arrangements  diverging  from  those  applicable 
to  government  operations  generally. 

In  the  development  of  appropriation  control,  the  first  step  was  the  in- 
troduction of  the  requirement  that  corporations  with  funds  available 
for  expenditure  without  annual  appropriation,  obtain  approval  by  the 
Bureau  of  the  Budget  of  expenditures  for  "administrative  expenses,"  a 
category  of  expenditure  somewhat  difficult  to  define.  On  August  5,  1935, 
the  President  directed  that  the  Federal  Savings  and  Loan  Insurance  Cor- 
poration, the  Home  Owners  Loan  Corporation,  and  the  Federal  Farm 
Mortgage  Corporation  submit  annually  to  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  esti- 
mates of  funds  needed  for  administrative  expenses,  and  that  they  incur 
obligations  only  within  the  limits  approved  by  the  budget  director.12 
Shortly  afterwards,  the  same  rule  was  applied  to  the  Federal  Deposit  In- 
surance Corporation,  the  Export-Import  Bank,  the  Reconstruction  Finance 

12  Executive  Order  No.  7126  of  August  5,  1935.   This  order  also  applied  to  several  non- 
corporate federal  agencies  which  were  at  the  time  outside  the  usual  appropriation  procedure. 


248  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

Corporation,  and  the  Electric  Home  and  Farm  Authority.13  Next,  the 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority  was  added  to  the  list.  In  1942,  the  require- 
ments were  extended  to  all  major  corporations  until  then  outside  the  rule.14 

The  next  step  in  the  evolution  of  overhead  control  of  government  cor- 
porations was  the  introduction  of  congressional  review  of  administrative 
expenses.  The  First  Deficiency  Appropriation  Act  of  1936  listed  nine 
larger  corporations  which,  beginning  with  the  next  fiscal  year,  were  pro- 
hibited from  incurring  any  administrative  expenses  "except  pursuant  to 
an  annual  appropriation  specifically  therefor  .  .  .  ,"15  This  provision  would 
have  resulted  in  expenditures  being  made  from  the  Treasury  rather  than 
from  corporate  funds.  That  in  turn  would  have  brought  such  adminis- 
trative expenditures  within  the  purview  of  the  Comptroller  General  and 
would  have  made  them  subject  to  all  the  general  rules  and  regulations 
applicable  to  departments.  However,  the  law  of  1936  was  modified  in 
subsequent  appropriation  acts.  Congressional  action  took  the  form  of  a 
limitation  on  the  amount  of  corporate  funds  which  might  be  spent  for 
administrative  purposes,  rather  than  of  an  appropriation  from  the  Treas- 
ury. Thus  the  language  of  one  pertinent  appropriation  act  for  1945  reads: 
"Not  to  exceed  $11,500,000  of  the  funds  of  the  Reconstruction  Finance 
Corporation,  established  by  the  Act  of  January  22,  1932  (47  Stat.  5),  shall 
be  available  during  the  fiscal  year  1945  for  its  administrative  expenses  .  .  . ." 
By  this  means,  Congress  limited  the  amount  which  might  be  spent  for 
administrative  purposes  but  did  not  bring  the  expenditure  under  the  control 
of  legislation  and  regulations  governing  ordinary  departments. 

Whether  or  not  the  original  laws  governing  a  corporation  should  be 
changed  to  bring  administrative  expenses  under  annual  congressional  re- 
view seems  to  have  been  determined  largely  by  chance  rather  than  by  prin- 
ciple. In  some  instances,  the  action  taken  resulted  clearly  from  the  lack 
of  legislative  confidence  in  a  particular  individual.  In  other  instances,  the 
initiative  came  from  the  corporation,  motivated  by  the  consideration  that 
it  might  be  better  off  under  a  limitation  suggested  by  itself  than  it  would 
be  under  more  drastic  action  initiated  by  Congress.16 

Subjection  of  "administrative  expenses"  to  congressional  limitation  was 
not  necessarily  onerous.  It  left  the  corporation  autonomous  in  the  greater 
part  of  its  fiscal  operations.  A  lending  corporation,  for  example,  might 
loan,  collect,  and  reloan  its  funds  without  congressional  limitation  on  the 

13  Executive  Order  No.  7150  of  August  19,  1935. 

**  Executive  Order  No.  9159  of  May  11,  1942. 

M  49  Stat.  1648. 

16  The  1946  budget  contemplated  that  congressional  limitation  would  be  placed  on  addi- 
tional corporations.  The  Chairman  of  the  Board  of  the  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation 
said  to  the  House  Appropriations  Committee:  "This  year,  to  comply  with  the  growing  senti- 
ment among  congressional  leaders  that  Congress  should  pass  upon  administrative  expenses  of 
Government  corporations,  we  voluntarily  submitted  our  annual  budget  for  such  expenses  for 
congressional  approval." 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  249 

total  scale  of  lending  operations— save  such  limitation  as  was  imposed  by 
the  amount  of  capital  available  to  the  corporation.  Congress  limited  only 
the  "administrative"  expenses.  Moreover,  the  ingenious  concept  of  "non- 
administrative  expenses"  and  their  exclusion  from  congressional  control 
permitted  corporate  flexibility  in  the  determination  of  the  amounts  spent 
for  certain  purposes  which  in  lay  language  might  be  called  administrative. 
The  differentiation  between  administrative  and  nonadministrative  expense 
was  not  sharp.  Generally,  continuing  overhead  costs  were  included  in  the 
administrative  category  while  expenses  arising  directly  in  the  management, 
protection,  and  care  of  property  by  the  corporation  were  nonadministrative. 

The  distinction  was  laid  down  in  the  appropriation  act  relating  to  each 
corporation.  Thus,  the  1945  appropriation  limitation  for  the  Reconstruc- 
tion Finance  Corporation  stated:  "Provided,  That  all  necessary  expenses 
in  connection  with  the  acquisition,  operation,  maintenance,  improvement, 
or  disposition  of  any  real  or  personal  property  belonging  to  the  Corpora- 
tion or  the  RFC  Mortgage  Company,  or  in  which  they  have  an  interest, 
including  expenses  of  collections  of  pledged  collateral,  shall  be  considered 
as  nonadministrative  expenses  for  the  purposes  hereof."  The  foregoing 
formula  is  typical,  but  variations  in  language  have  prevailed  for  each  cor- 
poration or  cluster  of  corporations  to  which  the  nonadministrative  expense 
proviso  applies.  The  significance  of  the  exception  of  nonadministrative 
expense  may  be  deduced  from  the  fact  that  in  1944  these  expenditures  for 
corporations  and  credit  agencies  reporting  them  were  in  the  aggregate  more 
than  five  times  as  great  as  administrative  expenses. 

Administrative  and  nonadministrative  expenses  may  be  very  small  in 
comparison  with  program  expenditures.  Before  1945,  program  expenditures 
of  most  corporations  were  excluded  from  annual  appropriation  control. 
However,  if  new  capital  or  additional  authority  to  borrow  was  necessary 
to  carry  out  a  program,  a  corporation  had  to  obtain  legislative  authority  and 
appropriations  to  enlarge  its  program.17  Thus,  when  the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority  needs  new  capital  to  construct  additional  works,  its  request  is 
scrutinized  by  Congress  just  as  thoroughly  as  a  similar  request  by  the 
Army  Corps  of  Engineers  or  the  Bureau  of  Reclamation  of  the  Depart- 
ment of  the  Interior.  If  program  expenditures,  however,  are  made  from 
funds  already  available  to  the  corporation,  the  more  general  practice  has 

17  Some  government  corporations  have  power  to  borrow  from  the  investing  public.  Such 
corporations  may  enlarge  their  sphere  of  activity  within  the  limits  of  their  borrowing  authority 
without  seeking  an  appropriation.  Thus  the  Federal  Land  Banks  finance  a  large  proportion 
of  their  mortgage  loans  from  funds  obtained  by  the  sale  of  securities.  Operating  costs  are 
met  and  profits  result  from  the  spread  between  the  rate  of  interest  the  banks  pay  and  the 
rate  they  receive.  The  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945  required  that  corpora- 
tions obtain  the  approval  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  before  selling  or  buying  obligations 
of  the  United  States  or  obligations  guaranteed  by  the  United  States  in  amounts  over  $100,000. 
Federal  Land  Banks  and  certain  other  agricultural  credit  corporations,  however,  were  merely 
required  to  consult  with  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury. 


250  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

been  that  no  annually  fixed  congressional  limitation  applied.18  Thus  de- 
posit losses  by  the  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation  have  not  been 
subject  to  appropriation  limitation.  The  Reconstruction  Finance  Corpora- 
tion has  been  able  to  loan,  collect,  and  reloan  its  funds  as  circumstances 
warranted  without  annual  permissive  action  by  Congress.  The  Smaller 
War  Plants  Corporation,  during  its  existence  in  World  War  II,  was  lim- 
ited by  Congress  in  its  administrative  expenditures,  but  its  capital  con- 
stituted a  revolving  fund  for  making  loans. 

Emerging  State  of  Budgetary  Control.  Our  discussion  of  the  state  of 
budgetary  control  over  government  corporations  must  necessarily  be  ten- 
tative, for  the  ultimate  developments  under  the  Government  Corporation 
Control  Act  of  1945  are  unpredictable.  That  act,  in  its  provisions  regard- 
ing the  submission  of  budget  requests,  represented  another  step  in  the 
evolution  of  the  types  of  control  already  described.  It  differentiated  between 
wholly  owned  and  mixed-ownership  government  corporations.  Insofar 
as  the  mixed-ownership  corporations  were  concerned — the  Central  Bank 
for  Cooperatives  and  the  Regional  Banks  for  Cooperatives,  Federal  Land 
Banks,  Federal  Home  Loan  Banks,  and  the  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Cor- 
poration— the  status  quo  was  maintained.  No  annual  budget  presentation 
was  required  of  these  corporations  by  the  act. 

Wholly  owned  government  corporations — that  is,  corporations  other 
than  those  of  mixed  ownership  listed  above— were  required  to  submit 
annually  a  "budget  program"  through  the  usual  budgetary  channels.  The 
act  specified:  "The  budget  program  shall  be  a  business-type  budget,  or  plan 
of  operations,  with  due  allowance  given  to  the  need  for  flexibility,  includ- 
ing provision  for  emergencies  and  contingencies,  in  order  that  the  cor- 
poration may  properly  carry  out  its  activities  as  authorized  by  law."  The 
statute  also  specified  that  the  budget  program  contain  a  statement  of  the 
financial  condition  of  the  corporation  and  other  information  calculated 
to  enable  Congress  to  evaluate  its  past  performance  and  its  future  program. 

The  degree  to  which  the  legislation  of  1945  will  actually  limit  corporate 
autonomy  can  be  determined  only  as  procedure  under  the  act  develops. 
The  act  did  not  contemplate  the  financing  of  corporate  activities  by  appro- 
priation from  the  Treasury.  Rather,  its  objective  was  to  furnish  opportunity 
for  congressional  review  of  planned  expenditures  from  corporate  funds. 
Thus  the  act  merely  applied  to  all  kinds  of  corporate  expenditures  the 
type  of  control  that  had  already  developed  with  regard  to  administrative 
expenses  of  many  corporations.  Incidentally,  it  was  assumed  that  corpora- 
tions which  had  been  operating  under  congressional  limitation  of  admin- 
istrative expenses  would  continue  to  do  so. 

The  degree  of  congressional  limitation  will  depend  in  large  measure  on 

.  18The  President's  budget  for  the  fiscal  year  of  1946  included  estimates  of  nonadminis- 
trative  expenses  and  program  expenditures  by  corporations,  but  these  figures  were  informational 
rather  than  in  request  of  congressional  authorization. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  251 

what  type  of  action  Congress  develops  the  habit  of  taking  after  it  receives 
corporate  budget  programs.  Congress  could  write  into  the  appropriation 
language  detailed  directions,  or  it  could  simply  do  nothing.  The  act  spe- 
cifically states  that  congressional  action  is  not  necessary  to  authorize 
expenditure  from  corporate  funds.  Congress  could,  if  it  wished,  examine 
the  programs  of  the  corporation.  If  the  plans  raised  no  issue,  inaction 
by  Congress  would  erect  no  bar  to  corporate  execution  of  programs.  How- 
ever, corporations  were  instructed  to  include  in  their  1947  budget  programs 
the  following  authorizing  language  to  be  transmitted  to  Congress:  "Ap- 
proval is  hereby  given  to  the  .  .  .  Corporation,  within  the  funds  available 
to  it,  to  undertake  the  types  of  programs  set  forth  in  its  1947  Budget." 

The  problem  remained  of  how  corporations  would  deal  with  unfore- 
seeable emergencies  requiring  rapid  change  of  plans.  It  was  proposed  to 
include  in  their  first  budget  program  presented  for  congressional  approval 
the  following  general  language  applicable  to  all  corporations:  "In  order  to 
meet  emergencies  or  contingencies  arising  subsequent  to  approval  of  the 
Budget  and  not  provided  for  in  the  budget  program,  a  corporation  covered 
by  the  provisions  of  this  Act  may  adjust,  with  the  approval  of  the  President, 
its  budget  program  to  provide  for  the  immediate  initiation  of  programs 
authorized  by  law  and  not  specifically  set  forth  in  the  approved  Budget; 
Provided,  That  the  new  program  shall  be  immediately  transmitted  to  the 
Congress  as  an  amendment  to  the  Budget;  Provided  further,  That  under 
no  circumstances  shall  a  corporation  prior  to  approval  by  the  Congress 
undertake  a  program  which  would  necessitate  an  increase  in  its  authorized 
borrowing  authority."19  Reference  to  the  President  implied  prior  review  by 
the  Budget  Bureau. 

Powers  of  the  Comptroller  General.  The  aspect  of  financial  control 
which  has  received  most  attention  is  that  of  the  audit  and  settlement  of 
accounts  by  the  Comptroller  General.  In  much  of  the  discussion  of  this 
subject  two  phases  of  the  matter  as  applied  to  corporations  are  not  clearly 
differentiated.  The  first  is  the  body  of  laws  and  regulations  applied  by 
the  Comptroller  General;  the  second  is  their  mode  of  application.  When 
expenditures  are  made  from  the  Treasury—as  contrasted  with  corporate 
funds — and  are  reviewed  by  the  Comptroller  General,  they  become  subject 
to  all  the  legal  prescriptions  of  government-wide  applicability  in  the  ab- 
sence of  positive  legislative  exception.  These  rules  are  frequently  in  them- 
selves not  conducive  to  efficiency  in  commercial  enterprise.  The  manner 
in  which  they  are  interpreted  and  the  methods  by  which  the  Comptroller 
General  applies  them  are  a  still  different  matter.  Highly  formalistic  pro- 

10  Such  a  proviso  was  reflective  of  the  spirit  in  which  the  House  Committeee  on  Expendi- 
tures in  the  Executive  Departments  expected  the  legislation  to  be  carried  out.  See  House  Report 
No.  856,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  July  5,  1945.  A  similar  provision  had  been  included  in  an 
earlier  bill  proposed  by  Senator  Byrd  (S.  469,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  February  5,  1945).  The 
hearings  on  this  bill  before  a  subcommittee  of  the  Senate  Committee  on  Banking  and  Cur- 
rency constitute  a  valuable  source  of  information  on  government  corporations. 


252  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

cedures  to  prove  compliance  place  a  great  burden  of  paperwork  on  govern- 
ment agencies.  Moreover,  the  discretion  which  rests  in  the  Comptroller 
General  in  the  interpretation  of  legislation  sometimes  makes  it  possible  for 
him  to  exert  great  influence  on  the  nature  of  an  agency's  program. 

A  weakness  of  the  Comptroller  General's  audit  as  it  applies  to  cor- 
porate enterprise  is  that  it  is  concerned  solely  with  legality  of  expenditure 
rather  than  with  efficiency  of  operation.  These  two  qualities  are  by  no 
means  identical.  A  government  agency  may  make  its  expenditures  in  a 
perfectly  legal  manner  and  yet  be  inefficient.  Thus,  to  spend  legally,  an 
agency  must  comply  with  an  act  requiring  competitive  bidding  in  the 
making  of  public  purchases.  If  all  bids  are  alike,  the  accepted  etiquette  is 
to  advertise  again  or  to  draw  lots  to  determine  the  successful  bidder.  David 
Lilienthal  points  out  that  if  this  procedure  had  been  required  of  the  Tenn- 
essee Valley  Authority  when  it  received  identical  bids  for  cement,  it  would 
have  had  to  pay  excessive  prices.  Instead  it  negotiated  lower  prices.  It 
was  able  to  bargain  with  the  intimation  that  it  could  construct  its  own 
cement  plant.20  Such  a  tactic  would  have  been  illegal  under  ordinary 
procedures,  and  the  Comptroller  General  would  have  blocked  payment  on 
a  purchase  so  made.  The  General  Accounting  Office  under  him  is  not 
concerned  with  the  operating  efficiency  of  a  purchasing  system;  it  seeks 
merely  to  see  that  particular  payments  have  been  made  in  accordance  with 
law.  Naturally,  in  commercial  enterprise  freedom  in  purchases  from  ham- 
pering routines  bulks  much  larger  in  importance  than  in  the  ordinary  depart- 
ment which  usually  has  to  make  only  small  purchases  for  its  office  needs. 

The  statute  on  purchasing  procedures  is  only  one  of  hundreds  of  stat- 
utes and  many  more  decisions  of  the  Comptroller  General  which  the  Gen- 
eral Accounting  Office  applies  in  reviewing  the  expenditures  of  government 
departments.  A  few  additional  illustrations  may  be  cited  of  such  general  pro- 
hibitions which  can  be  waived  in  particular  instances  only  by  congressional 
dispensation,  which,  needless  to  say,  has  been  often  granted.  Land  to  be 
used  for  public  buildings  may  not  be  bought  until  the  Attorney  General 
clears  the  title.  All  printing  must  be  done  by  the  Government  Printing 
Office.  Law  books  and  periodicals  may  not  be  purchased  except  by  specific 
appropriation.  All  contracts  must  be  placed  in  the  custody  of  the  General 
Accounting  Office.  Plans  for  public  buildings  must  be  approved  by  the 
Public  Buildings  Administration.  In  addition  to  general  laws  of  un- 
equivocal meaning,  government  departments  are  subject  to  a  large  body 
of  rulings  produced  by  the  General  Accounting  Office  in  the  interpretation 
of  statutory  language.21 

20  Lilienthal,  David  E.  and  Marquis,  R.  H.,  "The  Conduct  of  Business  Enterprises  by  the 
Federal  Government,"  Harvard  Law  Review,  1941,  Vol.  54,  p.  567. 

21  The  above  examples  are  from  McDiarmid,  John,  Government  Corporations  and  Federal 
Funds,  Chicago:   University  of  Chicago  Press,  1938.  This  able  treatment  covers  thoroughly  the 
general   problems  of  financial   control   sketched  here  only  briefly.    For  fuller  discussion,  see 
below  Ch.  25,  "Fiscal  Accountability." 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  253 

The  relationship  of  corporations  to  the  Comptroller  General  has  under- 
gone a  process  of  evolution  similar  to  that  of  their  relation  to  the  budget 
process  and  appropriation  procedure.  A  state  of  complete  freedom  from 
review  by  the  Comptroller  General  was  gradually  modified  by  changes 
affecting  particular  corporations.  Finally,  in  1945,  all  corporations  became 
subject  to  inspection  of  their  accounts  by  the  Comptroller  General  in  a 
manner  somewhat  different  from  that  applicable  to  ordinary  departments. 
Whether  a  corporation  came  within  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Comptroller 
General,  thus  being  subject  to  the  regulations  applied  by  his  office,  was 
determined  before  1945  by  the  basic  legislation  and  appropriation  language 
relating  to  each  corporation.  By  an  executive  order  of  1934,  the  President 
directed  that  corporations  created  after  March  3,  1933,  "the  accounting  pro- 
cedure for  which  is  not  otherwise  provided  by  law"  should  render  accounts 
to  the  General  Accounting  Office  for  settlement  as  prescribed  by  the  Comp- 
troller General.22  In  actual  fact,  the  procedure  was  generally  "otherwise 
provided  by  law"  for  each  corporation.23 

Nor  was  the  practice  by  any  means  uniform.  At  one  extreme,  corpora- 
tions such  as  the  Panama  Railroad  Company  and  the  Inland  Waterways 
Corporation,  both  created  before  the  date  fixed  by  the  executive  order  of 
1934,  retained  complete  freedom  from  the  Comptroller  General.  Even 
when  Congress  limited  total  administrative  expenses  for  particular  corpo- 
rations, it  sometimes  made  it  clear  that  this  action  did  not  bring  the  manner 
of  making  such  expenditures  within  the  regulations  applied  by  the  Comp- 
troller General.  Thus  the  1945  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  limita- 
tion indicated  that  "except  for  the  limitations  in  amounts  hereinbefore,  and 
the  restrictions  in  respect  to  travel  expenses,  the  administrative  expenses 
and  other  obligations  of  the  corporation  shall  be  incurred,  allowed,  and 
paid"  in  accordance  with  the  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  Act.  In 
other  instances,  administrative  expenses  alone  were  made  subject  to  review 
by  the  Comptroller  General.  Thus  the  1945  limitation  on  administrative 
expenses  of  the  Smaller  War  Plants  Corporation  provided  that  no  part  of 
the  administrative  expense  allowance  might  "be  obligated  or  expended 
unless  and  until  an  appropriate  appropriation  account  shall  have  been 
established  therefor  pursuant  to  an  appropriation  warrant  or  a  covering 
warrant,  and  all  such  expenses  shall  be  accounted  for  and  audited  in  ac- 
cordance with  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act." 

All  types  of  expenditures  by  Federal  Prison  Industries,  Inc.  were  placed 
under  review  by  the  Comptroller  General  and  had  to  be  made  "in  accord- 
ance with  the  laws  generally  applicable  to  the  expenditures  of  the  several 
departments  and  establishments  of  the  government."  The  Tennessee 

22  Executive  Order  No.  6549  of  January  3,  1934. 

23  A  table  showing  the  relationship  of  government  corporations  to  the  Bureau  of  the 
Budget  and  the  General  Accounting  Office  in  1944  is  printed  in  the  Hearings  of  the  Sub- 
committee of  the  House  Committee  on  Appropriations  on  the  Independent  Offices  Appropriation 
Bill  for  1945,  pp.  807-808. 


254  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

Valley  Authority  occupied  and  still  enjoys  a  peculiar  position  in  relation 
to  the  Comptroller  General.  Almost  continuously  since  its  establishment, 
TVA  has  been  in  controversy  with  the  Comptroller  General,  who  has  had 
as  allies  various  groups  hostile  to  its  program.  The  upshot  has  been  that 
TVA  is  liable  to  audit  by  the  Comptroller  General  but  that  Congress  has 
made  modifications  of  general  statutes  for  its  benefit.  Moreover,  TVA 
enjoys  by  statute  the  unique  right  to  overrule  a  disallowance  by  the  Comp- 
troller General  under  certain  circumstances.24 

Perhaps  good  and  sufficient  reasons  have  existed  for  excepting  the  ex- 
penditures of  many  government  corporations  from  general  laws  and  regu- 
lations. However,  one  of  the  consequences  has  been  an  unsatisfactory 
system  for  the  inspection  of  corporate  accounts.  Not  a  few  corporations 
have  employed  private  accounting  firms  to  examine  their  accounts.  This 
practice  is  of  dubious  efficacy  for  public  enterprise.  To  fill  the  void,  Con- 
gress in  its  legislation  of  1945  directed  the  Comptroller  General  to  audit  the 
financial  transactions  of  all  government  corporations,  but  the  intent  was 
to  require  a  type  of  audit  different  from  that  applicable  to  ordinary  depart- 
ments. When  the  Comptroller  General  "audits"  and  "settles"  accounts 
of  government  departments,  he  determines  whether  particular  expendi- 
tures have  been  made  in  accordance  with  law  and  regulation  as  inter- 
preted by  himself.  The  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  calls  for 
an  annual  audit  in  accordance  "with  the  principles  and  procedures  ap- 
plicable to  commercial  corporate  transactions." 

Thus  the  act  does  not  operate  to  bring  corporate  expenditures  under 
the  laws  and  regulations  applicable  to  government  departments  generally. 
The  status  quo  that  existed  before  the  passage  of  the  act  is  preserved.  If 
a  corporation  was  authorized  by  previous  legislation  to  determine  the  man- 
ner of  making  expenditures,  that  right  would  live  on.  Or  if  a  corporation 
was  bound  by  the  ordinary  rules  and  regulations,  as  in  the  example  cited 
above  of  Federal  Prison  Industries,  that  arrangement  would  also  continue. 
The  Comptroller  General  was  directed  to  report  to  Congress  on  the  find- 
ings of  the  audit,  including  ua  statement  of  assets  and  liabilities,  capital 
and  surplus,  or  deficit;  a  statement  of  surplus  or  deficit  analysis;  a  state- 
ment of  income  and  expense;  a  statement  of  sources  and  application  of 
funds;  and  such  comments  and  information  as  may  be  deemed  necessary 
to  keep  Congress  informed  of  the  operations  and  financial  condition  of  the 
several  corporations."25  The  statute  laid  the  basis  for  a  more  satisfactory 

24  An  act  of  1941  provides  that  the  General  Accounting  Office  "shall  not  disallow  credit 
for  nor  withhold  funds  because  of  any  expenditures  which  the  Board  shall  determine  to  have 
been  necessary"  to  carry  out  the  provisions  of  TVA's  basic  statute.  55  Stat.  775. 

25  The  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945  reenacted  in  substance  the  relevant 
sections  of  Public  Law  No.  4,  79th  Cong.,  approved  February  24,  ^945,  which  divorced  the 
Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  from  the  Department  of  Commerce  and  also  dealt  with  the 
audit  of  government  corporations.    Separation  of  the  RFC  from  the  Commerce  Department 
became  an  issue  in  connection  with  the  nomination  of  Henry  A.  Wallace  as  Secretary  of  Com- 
merce. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  255 

i 

financial  inspection  of  corporations  than  had  generally  prevailed.  At  the 
same  time,  the  General  Accounting  Office  was  faced  with  the  necessity  of 
radically  altering  its  approach  to  auditing  problems  in  order  to  achieve 
the  needed  results.26 

Central  Control  of  Personnel.  A  federal  department  is  bound  by 
general  legislation,  administered  by  the  Civil  Service  Commission,  which 
fixes  the  manner  of  recruitment  of  employees,  classification  and  pay 
scales,  and  other  aspects  of  personnel  administration.  As  a  consequence, 
departmental  discretion  is  limited  in  the  selection  of  staff  and  in  the 
determination  of  compensation  by  both  legislation  and  the  tradition  and 
customs  of  civil  service.  Government  corporations  have  placed  a  high  value 
on  freedom  from  civil  service  rules  and  procedures,  but  their  special  priv- 
ileges in  personnel  matters  are  rapidly  disappearing. 

The  President,  by  Executive  Order  No.  7915  of  June  24,  1938,  provided 
for  bringing  into  the  competitive  civil  service  all  positions,  "including 
positions  in  corporations  wholly  owned  or  controlled  by  the  United  States," 
except  those  exempted  by  statute.  The  general  terms  of  the  order  applied 
to  the  Commodity  Credit  Corporation,  the  Electric  Home  and  Farm 
Authority,  the  Export-Import  Bank,  and  the  Federal  Deposit  Insurance 
Corporation.27  The  Ramspeck  Act  of  1940  authorized  the  President  to 
place  in  the  competitive  classified  service  the  employees  of  all  government- 
owned  corporations  except  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority.28  The  Presi- 
dent exercised  this  power  by  Executive  Order  No.  8743  of  April  23,  1941, 
which  put  under  the  provisions  of  the  Civil  Service  Act  the  great 
majority  of  positions  to  which  the  act  of  1940  authorized  civil  service 
extension. 

In  the  legislation  creating  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  special  at- 
tention was  given  to  the  personnel  question.  Congress  concluded  that  the 
undertaking  might  have  a  smaller  chance  of  success  if  it  had  to  operate 
under  civil  service  rules,  yet  it  laid  down  the  following  merit-system  in- 
junction: "In  the  appointment  of  officials  and  the  selection  of  employees 
for  said  Corporation,  and  in  the  promotion  of  any  such  employees  or 
officials,  no  political  test  or  qualification  should  be  permitted  or  given 
consideration,  but  all  such  appointments  and  promotions  shall  be  given 
and  made  on  the  basis  of  merit  and  efficiency  .  .  .  ."  TVA  has  won  an 
impressive  reputation  for  its  personnel  policies  and  practices.  Its  reputa- 
tion has  spread  so  far,  wide,  and  handsome  that  in  recent  years  few  new  fed- 


26  For  a  discussion  of  the  operations  of  the  Comptroller  General,  see  below  Ch.  25,  "Fiscal 
Accountability,"  sec.  5,  "Audit." 

27  See  Pritchctt,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  384. 

2854  Stat.  1211.  The  statute  recognized  that  there  might  be  legal  limits  to  the  extension 
of  the  civil  service  laws  to  corporations  of  the  federal  government  formed  under  state  laws. 
On  the  problems  of  federal  corporations  and  state  legislative  control,  see  the  excellent  mono- 
graph by  Weintraub,  Ruth  G.,  Government  Corporations  and  State  Law,  New  York:  Columbia 
University  Press,  1939. 


256  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

cral  agencies  felt  respectable  unless  they  had  at  least  one  TVA  alumnus 
in  their  personnel  division.  A  thorough  student  of  TVA  concludes  that 
its  record  in  personnel  "has  been  in  considerable  measure  attributable  to 
its  freedom  from  time-worn  Civil  Service  procedures  and  regulations."29 
He  points  out,  however,  that  the  Civil  Service  Commission  of  today  is  not 
the  routine-ridden  organization  that  it  was  in  the  early  1930's. 

Freedom  from  the  "time-worn"  procedures  of  the  Civil  Service  Com- 
mission does  not  ensure  by  itself  better-than-average  personnel  practices. 
It  merely  leaves  the  way  open  for  innovation  and  managerial  responsibility 
in  personnel  administration.  In  some  instances — notably  the  Home  Own- 
ers Loan  Corporation  in  its  earlier  days — the  freedom  from  civil  service 
legislation  has  provided  merely  an  opening  for  spoils  practices.  No  cor- 
poration other  than  TVA  has  gained  an  outstanding  reputation  for  its 
personnel  policies,  although  some  may  have  done  a  good  job  without 
much  advertising. 

4.  CORPORATE  AUTONOMY  AND  POLITICAL  RESPONSIBILITY 

Legislative  Bewilderment.  The  highly  formalized  overhead  controls 
that  have  been  described  here  constitute  methods  by  which  agencies  may 
be  brought  within  the  orbit  of  general  governmental  policy.  When  these 
methods  do  not  apply  and  when  other  controls  are  absent,  presumably 
a  government-owned  corporation  would  possess  more  or  less  complete 
autonomy  within  the  limits  of  the  resources  and  authority  granted  to  it 
at  the  time  of  its  creation.  The  theory  of  corporate  autonomy  may  thus 
conflict  with  the  necessity  that  public  activities  be  in  accord  with  the 
policies  and  wishes  of  those  who  carry  political  responsibility  for  the  actions 
of  government.  Or,  to  put  the  proposition  in  another  way,  it  is  funda- 
mental that  means  exist  by  which  administrative  officers  and  governmental 
agencies  may  be  held  accountable  for  their  acts  to  those  who  bear  political 
responsibility — the  chief  executive  and  the  legislature.  In  terms  of  manage- 
ment, means  must  exist  by  which  the  operations  of  the  corporation  may 
be  brought  into  harmony  with  related  actions  of  government. 

Of  course,  the  establishment  of  a  corporation  with  the  concomitant 
definition  of  its  functions — the  instruction  about  what  it  is  to  do — is  in 
itself  an  act  of  direction.  It  is  impracticable,  however,  for  Congress  and 
the  President,  or  an  agency  head  acting  pursuant  to  law,  to  create  a  cor- 
poration, tell  it  what  to  do,  and  then  forget  about  it.  As  a  matter  of 
political  necessity,  there  must  be  a  continuing  general  surveillance  of  its 
operations.  The  government  corporation,  if  it  enjoys  financial  autonomy, 
is  removed  from  the  annual  executive  and  legislative  review  of  requests  for 

^Pritchctt,  C.  H.,  The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  p.  306,  Chapel  Hill:  University  of 
North  Carolina  Press,  1943. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  257 

appropriations.  If  it  is  removed  from  general  administrative  supervision,  it  is 
apt— as  is  frequently  charged— to  consider  itself  not  a  part  of  government. 

Congress  is  somewhat  baffled  in  its  dealings  with  government  corpo- 
rations. They  do  not  yield  very  well  to  the  types  of  control  exercised  over 
government  departments.  In  dealing  with  the  ordinary  agency,  a  con- 
gressional committee  can  tell  it  how  many  employees  of  particular  grades 
it  can  employ  during  the  next  fiscal  year,  can  reduce  the  amount  available 
for  the  salary  of  an  official  it  dislikes,  can  periodically  put  the  key  officers 
on  the  carpet,  and  can  enter  into  a  very  searching  review  of  the  agency's 
plans  and  proposals.  In  general,  Congress  is  thus  able  actually  to  exercise 
control — although  interference  with  the  minutiae  of  administration  is  not 
a  genuine  control  of  broad  policy.  On  the  other  hand,  when  Congress 
comes  up  against  a  corporation  operating  a  commercial  enterprise,  differ- 
ent types  of  evaluation  of  performance  are  essential.  To  criticize  and  to 
demand  more  effective  management  of  such  an  enterprise  would  not  lead 
very  far  if  the  usual  types  of  analysis  of  government  operations  were  fol- 
lowed. 

A  sense  of  frustration  seems  to  arise  among  Congressmen  when  they 
are  concerned  with  government  corporations.  The  following  exchange 
before  a  congressional  committee  between  Senator  Byrd  as  its  chairman, 
and  Jesse  Jones,  then  Secretary  of  Commerce  and  boss  of  the  Reconstruc- 
tion Finance  Corporation,  is  a  good  illustration: 

The  Chairman.  Will  you  point  out  to  me  now  exactly  what  con- 
gressional authority  Congress  has  over  these  corporations  after  the 
first  authorization  to  operate  is  given  to  you?  .  .  .  We  authorize  you  to 
borrow  $5,000,000,000.  After  that  is  done,  what  authority  has  Con- 
gress over  the  RFC  and  how  can  they  exercise  it  if  it  has  got  it? 

Secretary  Jones.  I  suppose  if  we  misuse  the  funds,  you  would  have 
a  good  deal  of  authority? 

The  Chairman.    How? 

Secretary  Jones.   I  do  not  know  about  that. . . . 

•    •    •    • 

The  Chairman. ...  I  am  asking  you  what  authority  Congress  has  over 
the  RFC  after  they  make  their  initial  authorization. 

Secretary  Jones.    I  have  always  thought  they  had  all  of  the  authority. 

The  Chairman.  Tell  me  how  they  can  exercise  the  authority.  You 
know  vastly  more  about  it  than  I  do.  They  haven't  even  a  report  from 
the  RFC  in  detail. 

Secretary  Jones.    We  make  monthly  reports  to  Congress. 

The  Chairman.   You  do  not  make  them  in  detail? 

Secretary  Jones.   Pretty  well  in  detail. 

The  Chairman.  You  do  not  give  the  names  of  the  borrowers? 

Secretary  Jones.  I  think  we  do 


258  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

The  Chairman.    Where  does  that  report  go? 

Mr.  Mulligan.    To  the  Vice-President  and  the  Speaker. 

The  Chairman.   Is  it  a  public  report? 

Mr.  Mulligan.  Yes,  except  since  the  war  I  do  not  know  whether 
they  have  been  issued  to  the  general  public  or  not. 

The  Chairman.    Do  you  make  an  annual  report  to  Congress? 

Mr.  Mulligan.  In  addition  to  the  monthly  report  a  quarterly  report 
to  Congress  is  also  required  by  law. 

Secretary  Jones.    A  monthly  report  and  a  quarterly  report. .  .  . 

The  Chairman.  ...  I  have  never  seen  a  report  on  the  itemized  loans 
of  the  RFC. 

Secretary  Jones.  If  you  will  refer  to  the  act,  Senator,  you  will  find  it 
requires  these  things,  and  these  reports  are  sent  in  here,  and  you  can  go 
to  the  Vice-President's  office  and  get  them. 

The  Chairman.    I  am  glad  to  hear  you  say  that. 

Secretary  Jones.  We  will  be  delighted  to  send  them  to  the  individual 
members  that  want  them.  .  .  . 

The  Chairman.    I  am  talking  about  the  itemized  statements. 

Secretary  Jones.  I  am  talking  about  the  itemized  statement.  I  am 
talking  about  the  loan  to  John  Smith  for  X  dollars,  and  the  rate  of 
interest.  .  .  . 

The  Chairman.  You  haven't  told  me  yet  what  control  Congress  can 
exercise  over  the  RFC. 

Secretary  Jones.    I  will  leave  that  to  Congress.30 

Political  Antagonisms.  Congress  is  not,  of  course,  as  helpless  as  the 
Senator  would  have  us  believe  in  the  foregoing  passage.  However,  it  is 
certainly  true  that  the  legislature  has  not  developed  satisfactory  ways  and 
means  for  a  recurring  review  of  the  operations  of  corporations.  The  normal 
courses  of  discussion  and  criticism  are  open;  when  a  Senator  thunders, 
government  officials  quake  in  their  boots,  whether  they  be  on  corporate 
or  on  noncorporate  payrolls.  Congress  has  at  its  disposal  the  investigative 
power  which  has  been  used  effectively  in  relation  to  the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority,  the  Home  Owners  Loan  Corporation,  and  other  corporations. 

At  times,  the  intervention  of  Congress  is  not  calculated  to  guide  gen- 
eral policy  but  to  gain  partisan,  personal,  or  local  advantage.  Thus,  over 
several  congressional  sessions  Senator  McKellar  of  Tennessee  has  con- 
ducted warfare  against  TV  A,  attempting  to  bring  its  employees  under 
Senate  confirmation,  to  deprive  it  of  the  use  of  its  receipts,  and  in  general 
to  limit  the  authority  of  the  corporation.  The  Senator  was  said  to  be  intent 
upon  patronage  and  to  cloak  a  personal  grudge  against  the  chairman  of 
TV  A,  a  man  not  disposed  to  be  pliable  when  he  felt  that  the  interests  of 


3°  Joint  Committee  on  Reduction  of  Non-Essential   Federal  Expenditures,  Hearings,  pp. 
2295-2297,  78th  Cong.,  1st  Scss.,  pt.  7,  1943. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  259 

the  corporation  were  threatened.31  This  sort  of  congressional  intervention 
is  probably  the  very  thing  which  advocates  of  the  corporate  method  desire 
to  avoid  by  autonomy.  Yet  the  most  liberal  corporate  freedom  will  not 
serve  to  stave  off  congressional  attack  on  either  partisan  or  policy  grounds. 
The  political  battle  has  to  be  won  for  any  activity,  whether  or  not  it  is 
conducted  through  corporate  form. 

It  should  be  well  noted  also  that  most  of  the  corporations  have  been  at 
fault  at  various  times  in  their  relationships  with  Congress.  They  have 
partaken  in  a  special  degree  of  the  administrative  attitude  that  "what  Con- 
gress does  not  know  will  not  get  one  into  trouble."  If  corporations  expect 
to  enjoy  a  status  different  from  that  of  a  usual  department,  they  must 
furnish  information  by  which  Congress  can  evaluate  their  operations  by 
means  different  from  those  applied  to  the  ordinary  department.  The  chair- 
man of  TVA  has  recognized  this  need  and  has  proposed  that  special 
arrangements  be  made  by  which  at  appropriate  intervals  Congress  could 
review  the  work  of  corporations.32 

Providing  Information  for  the  Legislature.  A  better  flow  of  informa- 
tion has  been  reaching  Congress  since  the  middle  thirties.  Principally 
through  the  stimulus  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  Non-Essential  Expendi- 
tures, comprehensive  quarterly  financial  reports  are  made  by  the  corpora- 
tions to  the  Treasury  and  to  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget.33  Such  reports  are 
intelligible  to  technically  competent  persons,  but  they  are  not  a  very  effec- 
tive method  of  informing  Congress  or  the  public.  The  President's  budget 
annually  contains  a  statement  for  each  corporation  showing  expenditures 
and  receipts,  actual  and  anticipated,  just  as  for  ordinary  departments.34 
Some  of  the  corporations  publish  annual  reports.  Among  the  more  illumi- 
nating reports  are  those  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority. 

Generally,  however,  the  work  of  the  corporations  has  been  a  closed 
book  to  Congress.  Take  the  annual  report  of  the  Inland  Waterways  Cor- 
poration as  an  example.  It  is  prepared  along  traditional  lines  of  corporate 
reporting;  but  even  private  corporations  have  discovered  that  they  must 
call  in  their  public-relations  advisers  as  well  as  their  accountants  to  try  to 
make  their  reports  intelligible  to  their  stockholders.  The  average  Con- 
gressman— or  the  average  citizen — can  sweat  over  the  report  of  the  Inland 
Waterways  Corporation  for  1943  and  find  that  it  had  a  small  deficit  in  its 
transport  operations  which  was  offset  by  profits  realized  from  the  sale  of 
securities  of  the  federal  government.  However,  from  the  report  it  is  difficult 
to  evaluate  the  efficiency  of  the  management.  Was  it  more  or  less  effective 


51  See  Reynolds,  J.  L.,  "McKellar  on  the  Rampage,"  New  Republic,  March  27 \  1944,  Vol. 
110,  pp.  400-402. 

32  Lilienthal  and  Marquis,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  20. 

33  For  the  present  form  of  these  reports,  see  Budget-Treasury  Regulation  No.  3  of  Sep- 
tember 1,  1944,  adopted  under  Executive  Order  No.  8512  of  August  13,  1940. 

3*  Accompanying  the  fiscal  statements  are  brief  statements  of  the  functions  and  authority 
of  the  corporations.  This  is  a  convenient  source  of  data  on  the  current  status  of  the  corporations. 


260  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

than  in  the  preceding  year?  Was  the  corporation  gradually  going  bank- 
rupt through  the  impairment  of  its  capital?85  What  could  be  done  to  im- 
prove the  income-expense  ratio? 

The  Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation  issues  an  excellent  annual 
report.  Still,  nowhere  does  it  show  how  much  this  corporation  is  costing 
the  government  in  terms  of  the  annual  interest  charge  on  capital  stock, 
subscribed  by  the  Treasury,  which  yields  no  return  to  the  federal  govern- 
ment. In  most  instances  it  requires  prolonged  special  study  to  dig  up  the 
really  pertinent  facts  for  the  evaluation  of  corporate  operations.  Thus,  by 
enough  research  to  produce  a  book,  a  private  scholar  might  conclude  that 
without  the  subsidy  from  the  Production  Credit  Corporations,  the  production 
credit  associations  would  have  had  to  charge  farmers  about  one  per 
cent  more  on  loans  in  1943  in  order  to  maintain  the  same  services  and 
accumulate  the  same  reserves  as  in  1942.36  Such  data  are  not  ordinarily 
produced  by  corporate  reporting. 

Congress  should  become  better  informed  on  the  workings  of  govern- 
ment corporations  by  the  procedures  provided  under  the  Government  Coi- 
poration  Control  Act  of  1945.  It  will  receive  and  review  the  annual  budget 
programs  of  wholly  owned  government  corporations.  It  will  also  be  pre- 
sented with  reports  of  annual  audits  by  the  Comptroller  General  of  the 
affairs  of  both  wholly  owned  and  mixed-ownership  corporations.  These 
arrangements  will  bring  the  business  of  each  corporation  before  Congress 
as  a  matter  of  routine.  They  will  furnish  corporate  officials  with  the 
opportunity  to  explain  their  operations,  without  waiting  until  a  hostile  in- 
vestigation arises — caused  perhaps  in  part  because  of  lack  of  better  channels 
of  communication  between  the  corporation  and  Congress.  In  February, 
1946,  the  House  Committee  on  Appropriations  created  a  new  subcommit- 
tee to  deal  with  corporate  budget  programs  and  reports — a  recognition  of 
the  necessity  for  specialization  within  the  committee  on  the  problems  of 
corporations. 

Enforcing  Political  Responsibility  of  Government  Corporations.  The 
broader  question  of  responsibility  has  not  been  realistically  faced  by  gov- 
ernment-corporation enthusiasts.37  The  analogy  with  the  private  corpora- 

35  Inadequate  information  on  the  state  of  the  assets  of  a  corporation  may  conceal  losses  or 
it  may  result  in  continued  overcapitalization  which  is,  of  course,  costly  to  government.  A 
statute  of  1938  provided  for  an  annual  appraisal  of  the  net  worth  of  the  Commodity  Credit 
Corporation.  Impairment  of  capital  would  be  restored  by  appropriation,  thus  bringing  losses  to 
the  attention  of  Congress.  Increment  of  assets  above  the  authorized  capital  would  be  covered 
into  the  Treasury,  thus  cutting  off  the  cost  of  excess  capital  in  the  hands  of  the  corporation. 
The  President  in  1939,  in  his  budget  for  the  fiscal  year  of  1940  (p.  ix),  recommended  that  the 
practice  be  extended  to  other  corporations.  The  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  requires 
that  corporate  budget  programs  include  estimates  of  capital  to  be  returned  to  the  Treasury  or 
of  appropriations  required  to  restore  capital  impairments. 

86  Butz,  E.  L.,  The  Production  Credit  System  for  Farmers,  Washington:  Brookings  Institu- 
tion, 1944. 

87  The  questions  that  need  to  be  answered  have  been  posed.   See  Committee  on  Public 
Administration,  Research  in  the  Use  of  the  Government  Corporation,  New  York,  1940. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  261 

tion  is  not  perfect.  Although  a  degree  of  autonomy  is  enjoyed  by  a  private 
corporation,  a  variety  of  forces  operates  to  enforce  responsibility.  The 
financial  journals,  bankers,  investment  advisers,  and  such  government 
agencies  as  the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  seek  and  obtain  con- 
siderable information  about  the  operation  of  a  business  concern.  Larger 
stockholders  are  certainly  not  without  influence.  The  need  to  retain  the 
confidence  of  the  financial  community  operates  as  a  spur  to  management. 
The  mores  and  habits  of  a  business  civilization  likewise  have  their  effects. 

These  influences  are  normally  not  present  in  the  case  of  a  government 
corporation.  No  very  satisfactory  substitutes  have  been  evolved  save  for 
those  corporations,  such  as  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  which  have 
been  centers  of  controversy  and  have  thus  been  compelled  to  exert  their  best 
efforts  both  to  manage  their  affairs  and  to  inform  the  public  of  the  results. 
Had  the  practice  of  relying  on  private  capital  as  a  partial  method  of 
financing  become  more  general,  government  corporations  would  have  had 
to  go  into  the  market  and  sell  their  securities  like  private  concerns.  Under 
such  conditions,  they  might  have  become  subject  to  the  discipline  of  the 
financial  market.  This  has  been  true  of  the  Federal  Land  Banks  and 
certain  other  lending  corporations.  But  the  more  general  practice  has  been 
to  finance  government  corporate  operations  solely  with  public  funds. 

The  theory  of  corporate  autonomy  has  been  more  badly  mangled  by  the 
integration  of  corporations  into  the  departmental  system  than  through  con- 
trol by  Congress.  This  integration  comes  about  partially  through  neces- 
sity. It  is  impracticable  to  permit  scores  of  corporations  to  drift  about  the 
administrative  cosmos  accountable  to  no  one  in  particular.  From  an  operat- 
ing standpoint,  it  is  also  essential  that  corporate  policies  be  geared  into 
related  policies  executed  by  ordinary  departments.  The  simplest  way  to 
accomplish  such  reconciliation  is  by  bringing  the  corporation  within  the 
appropriate  department.  Thus,  Federal  Prison  Industries,  Inc.  is  within 
the  Department  of  Justice  and  is  managed  by  those  responsible  for  the 
federal  prisons.  The  Farm  Credit  Administration  has  been  within  the  De- 
partment of  Agriculture  and  has  functioned  primarily  as  something  ap- 
proximating a  holding  company.  Its  supervision  of  the  farm  credit  corpora- 
tions has  represented,  in  part,  a  specialized  substitute  for  other  overhead 
controls. 

Most  of  the  housing  corporations  are  within  the  structure  of  the  Na- 
tional Housing  Agency.  The  integration  of  the  Defense  Plant  Corpora- 
tion, the  Defense  Supplies  Corporation,  the  Metals  Reserve  Company  and 
other  defense  subsidiaries  of  the  Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  has 
been  accomplished  by  means  other  than  assignment  to  the  appropriate  de- 
partment. In  the  exercise  of  its  general  powers  over  procurement,  the  War 
Production  Board  certified  plants  to  be  constructed,  supplies  to  be  pur- 
chased, and,  in  some  instances,  subsidies  to  be  paid.  These  corporations 
acted  as  bankers  and  managers  to  carry  out  decisions  made  elsewhere.  In 


262  GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS 

their  cases,  the  concept  of  a  corporate  board  of  directors  fixing  the  policy 
of  the  corporation  and  exercising  an  autonomous  prudence  was  thus  far 
removed  from  the  actual  administrative  situation. 

The  integration  of  corporations  into  the  general  administrative  struc- 
ture has  been  carried  far.  It  may  even  be  concluded  that,  by  and  large, 
a  government  corporation,  insofar  as  its  autonomy  in  policy  is  concerned, 
is  little  different  from  a  bureau  or  other  subdivision  of  a  department.  The 
Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation  and  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority 
retain  their  independent  identity,  but  they  are  exceptional.  The  corpora- 
tion today  usually  enjoys  certain  special  privileges  that  a  departmental 
bureau  does  not  have.  However,  in  the  exercise  of  these  privileges  it  must 
in  most  instances  be  guided  by  departmental  policy  and  direction. 

The  Contribution  of  the  Corporate  Device.  In  reality  there  are  few,  if 
any,  corporate  operations  which  could  not  be  accomplished  by  an  ordinary 
department  if  the  usual  financial  procedures  were  modified.38  Corpora- 
tions have  tended  to  acquire  some  of  the  characteristics  of  the  ordinary 
department,  thereby  narrowing  the  differences  between  the  two.  Never- 
theless, most  corporations  do  retain  certain  distinguishing  features.  Be- 
fore the  passage  of  the  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945,  prob- 
ably the  most  important  privileges  accorded  to  many  corporations  were 
freedom  from  the  annual  appropriating  process  for  the  major  part  of  their 
outlays,  and  the  right  to  retain  receipts  for  corporate  use.  The  extent  to 
which  procedures  under  this  act  will  modify  the  autonomy  of  corporations 
remains  to  be  seen,  but  the  legislation  contemplates  different  arrangements 
for  corporations  than  for  ordinary  departments.  Of  comparable  import- 
ance is  freedom  from  review  by  the  Comptroller  General,  which  is  of  very 
great  significance  in  the  negotiation  and  settlement  of  contracts  and  other 
business  transactions.  If  the  Government  Corporation  Control  Act  really 
results  in  a  "commercial"  type  of  audit,  it  will  not  narrow  corporate  priv- 
ileges in  this  regard. 

Almost  all  the  supposedly  desirable  features  of  corporations  can  be,  and 
from  time  to  time  have  been,  given  to  ordinary  departments.  It  is  possible 
in  this  manner  to  establish  a  revolving  fund  into  which  receipts  are  paid 
and  from  which  expenditures  are  made;  to  exempt  employees  from  civil 
service  regulations;  to  deprive  the  Comptroller  General  of  his  powers  with 
respect  to  certain  types  of  transactions;  and  to  make  exceptions  from  other 
types  of  legislative  and  executive  controls.  Nevertheless,  it  has  been  much 
easier  to  accomplish  these  things  by  creating  a  corporation  than  by  making 
an  open  and  frontal  assault  on  generally  accepted  working  rules  governing 
the  entire  administrative  establishment. 

Perhaps  the  chief  justification  of  the  corporate  device  is  that  in  times 

38  For  a  careful  comparative  analysis  of  corporations  and  their  equivalents  in  ordinary 
departments,  see  White,  Leonard  D.,  Introduction  to  the  Study  of  Public  Admin  ttration,  ch.  9, 
New  York:  Macmillan,  rev.  cd.,  1939. 


GOVERNMENT  CORPORATIONS  263 

of  emergency  it  has  been  possible  to  achieve  with  it  urgent  objectives  which 
might  have  been  more  difficult  or  impossible  of  attainment  by  other  means. 
By  a  single  action — establishment  of  the  corporation — men  have  been  put 
to  work  on  a  job  unhampered  by  the  necessity  of  conducting  a  running 
fight  with  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  the  Appropriations  Committees,  the 
Comptroller  General,  and  the  Civil  Service  Commission.  Once  the  emer- 
gency is  over  and  the  operation  is  proceeding  smoothly,  the  corporation 
can  be  brought  into  more  orthodox  governmental  patterns,  or  it  can  be 
liquidated. 

The  wide  use  of  the  corporation  and  the  considerable  literature  on  the 
subject  throw  into  bold  relief  the  general  problem  of  administrative  decon- 
centration.  The  pressure  toward  uniformity  of  operating  method  and 
toward  coordination  of  policy  throughout  the  huge  federal  machinery 
brings  with  it  formidable  issues  in  the  maintenance  of  initiative  and  in 
the  preservation  of  conditions  favorable  to  self-reliant  management  and 
innovation.  Unification  and  uniformity  carry  with  them  an  inevitable 
degree  of  congestion  at  the  center,  and  also  delay  and  hamper  action.  In 
devising  mechanisms  for  central  control  we  must  guard  against  the  ten- 
dency to  exert  great  effort  in  the  achievement  of  integration  and  uniformity 
with  respect  to  matters  that  really  are  not  of  sufficient  significance  to  justify 
he  trouble. 

The  rise  of  the  government  corporation  reflects  the  difficulties  that  sur- 
round responsive  administration  in  the  settled  forms  of  the  departmental 
system  and  in  higher  central  controls.  Escape  from  traditional  ways  of 
doing  things  through  corporate  autonomy  is  not  the  answer.  The  solution 
lies  in  better  appreciation  of  the  need  for  creative  freedom  of  public  manage- 
ment buttressed  by  full  responsibility — and  for  forms  of  control  appropriate 
to  this  fundamental  purpose. 


CHAPTER 


Field  Organization 


Capitals  of  nations  and  states  are  popularly  regarded  as  the  places  where 
the  business  of  government  is  carried  on.  Actually  this  business  brings 
national  and  state  government  into  hundreds  and  thousands  of  communi- 
ties distant  from  the  capital — that  is,  into  "the  field."  For  it  is  in  the  field 
that  taxes  are  collected,  regulatory  laws  enforced,  and  governmental  serv- 
ices rendered.  This  being  true,  effective  administration  at  the  capital  is 
not  enough.  Equally  important  is  the  condition  of  the  field  service.  It 
must  be  competently  staffed.  It  must  contribute  to  the  planning  and  execu- 
tion of  the  programs  of  the  various  departments  and  bureaus  centered  at 
the  capital.  It  must  bring  these  more  or  less  specialized  programs  into 
coordinated  focus  for  each  geographic  area  cf  the  country.  It  must  be 
responsive  to  local  as  well  as  national  needs, 

1.  THE  GROWTH  OF  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

Continental  Prototypes.  Historically,  field  organization  has  been  a  tool 
used  for  both  the  centralization  and  decentralization  of  government.  The 
centralist  emphasis  dominated  field  organization  during  the  centuries  when 
Western  civilization  was  emerging  from  the  Middle  Ages.  The  evolution 
of  the  nation-state  was  a  reaction  against  the  feudal  organization  of  society 
— under  which  state  taxes  had  long  ceased  to  be  collected,  justice  was  meted 
out  by  local  authorities,  the  right  to  travel  highways  depended  on  payment 
of  tolls  to  local  lords,  the  coinage  of  money  was  far  from  a  state  monopoly, 
and  national  armies  were  mere  assemblages  of  groups  of  vassals  of  allied 
lords.  Naturally,  the  extent  of  reversal  of  these  centrifugal  tendencies  has 
depended  upon  the  king's  capacity  for  reducing  his  dependence  upon 
the  feudal  lords.  This  required,  among  other  things,  the  development  of 
a  truly  national  bureaucracy  that  would  carry  the  king's  law  and  collect 
the  king's  taxes  throughout  the  realm. 

Accordingly,  in  France  for  instance,  the  king  appointed  so-called  in- 
tendants  to  represent  him  in  the  provinces,  with  authority  over  both  local 

264 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  263 

governments  and  subordinate  field  officials  of  the  different  departments 
of  the  national  government.1  The  precedent  thus  set  by  the  ancien  regime 
was  not  neglected  after  the  Revolution  of  1789.  Indeed,  Napoleon  later 
improved  upon  this  centralizing  device.  The  king's  intendants,  serving 
for  twenty  or  thirty  years  in  their  particular  provinces,  had  often  asserted 
a  measure  of  independence  from  the  Paris  government  by  encouraging  and 
defending  local  interests.  Napoleon,  noting  these  difficulties,  deliberately 
ignored  the  provinces,  superimposing  on  the  country's  map  an  entirely 
artificial  set  of  boundaries  outlining  areal  "departments,"  each  of  which 
was  headed  by  a  prefect  representing  the  central  government.  This  scheme 
of  territorial  administration  has  continued  since  Napoleon's  time  as  a 
major  instrument  of  centralization.  Its  distinctive  feature  is  that  the  pre- 
fect represents  practically  all  of  the  national  government's  functional  de- 
partments. Consequently,  most  of  the  functional  threads  of  national  gov- 
ernment are  pulled  together  at  his  level  before  they  are  stretched  on  to 
individual  communities  and  citizens. 

In  Prussia,  too,  and  its  precursor,  the  Electorate  of  Brandenburg,  field 
officers  were  used  to  weld  local  feudatories  into  a  centralized  nation.  Fred- 
erick William,  the  Great  Elector  of  Brandenburg,  in  1657  divided  his 
Privy  Council  into  a  larger  number  of  specialized  departments,  and  des- 
ignated certain  members  of  the  council  as  local  regents.  Characteristically, 
the  regents  were  not  natives  of  the  areas  to  which  they  were  assigned. 
Being  tied  both  to  the  Privy  Council  and  to  local  areas,  the  regents  were 
effective  instruments  for  insuring  local  observance  of  national  economic, 
social,  and  fiscal  policies.  By  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century,  the 
regents  had  associated  with  them  administrative  councils  for  their  areas, 
composed  of  national  field  agents. 

<  Simultaneously  with  the  development  of  the  local  regents  and  their 
administrative  councils,  there  developed  war  commissariats  scattered 
throughout  the  country,  whose  concern  for  financing,  feeding,  billeting, 
and  clothing  the  armed  forces  of  the  military-minded  Prussian  state  made 
them  strong  rivals  of  the  regents  and  councils.  As  friction  between  the 
rival  establishments  increased,  the  successive  kings  issued  ineffectual  man- 
dates directing  the  commissariats  and  councils  to  confer  with  each  other 
in  order  to  avoid  wasteful  competition,  and  even  introduced  royal  arbitra- 
tion of  individual  jurisdictional  conflicts.  Despairing  of  these  measures,  the 
king  ultimately  merged  the  councils  and  the  commissariats.  As  a  result, 
the  more  aggressive  war  commissariats  gained  dominance  over  the  coun- 
cils, and  the  Prussian  field  service  became  even  more  of  a  centralizing 
force.2 

1  Cf.  Bloch,  Marc,  "Feudalism:  European,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Vol.  6, 
pp.  203-210;  Shepard,  W.  J.,  "Centralization,"  ibid.,  Vol.  3,  pp.  308-312;  Finer,  Herman, 
Theory  and  Practice  of  Modern  Government,  pp.  1223  ff.,  London:  Methucn,  1932. 

»C/.  Finer,  ibid.,  pp.  1190-1195,  1202. 


266  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

British  Development.  Considerably  before  the  European  continent 
emerged  from  feudalism,  England  had  established  the  ultimate  dependence 
of  all  lords  and  lords'  vassals  upon  the  king.  Accordingly,  she  never  was 
driven  to  provide  the  continental  type  of  counterpoise  to  the  decentralized 
structure  of  feudalism— an  army  of  intendants  or  regents  administering 
local  areas  on  behalf  of  the  king.  Instead  centralist  tendencies  took  the 
form  of  local  sheriffs  designed  both  to  represent  the  king  and  to  protect 
the  rights  of  local  self-government  against  encroachment  by  feudal  lords; 
or  of  justices  of  the  peace  appointed  by  the  king  from  among  local  land- 
owners. However,  popular  prejudice  against  the  sheriffs  as  local  representa- 
tives of  the  king  resulted  in  decay  of  the  sheriff's  office.  Subsequently,  the 
attempt  to  use  local  justices  of  the  peace  as  royal  administrative  agents  came 
to  an  end  with  the  civil  wars  of  the  seventeenth  century.  Thenceforth  the 
justices  were  virtually  uncontrolled  by  London. 

Throughout  British  development,  emphasis  was  placed  on  struggles 
over  policy  formation  and  therefore  over  the  role  of  Parliament.  The  rela- 
tively lighter  stress  placed  upon  the  machinery  through  which  policies 
would  be  administered  may  account  for  the  British  failure  to  follow  the 
continental  pattern  of  field  integration.  In  recent  times,  extension  of  the 
national  government  to  the  field  has  been  through  the  individual  functional 
departments,  not  through  agents  representing  the  whole  national  adminis- 
tration in  particular  areas.3 

Expansion  of  Federal  Functions.  In  modern  times  particularly,  it  is  diffi- 
cult to  disentangle  the  motives,  or  for  that  matter  the  results,  of  the  growth 
of  field  services.  To  some  degree  the  centralizing  factor — so  conspicuous  in 
the  modern  origins  of  field  organization— persists,  often  with  emphasis 
upon  supervision  of  local  governments.  At  the  other  extreme  is  a  conscious 
effort  by  national  governments  to  permit  adaptation  of  administration  to 
the  needs  and  aspirations  of  particular  regions— in  other  words,  to  decen- 
tralize the  execution  of  policies  that  must  be  formulated  nationally.  A  third, 
and  perhaps  most  important  factor  in  the  growth  of  field  organization, 
is^  simply  the  need  to  get  particular  functions  performed,  with  all  conscious 
theorizing  about  centralization  and  decentralization  pushed  aside. 

This  third  factor  has  dominated  the  development  of  the  field  service  of 
our  federal  government.  In  the  United  States,  the  centralization-decentrali- 
zation dispute  has  centered  on  the  respective  powers  of  the  Union  and  the 
states.  The  federal  field  service  has  been  generally  accepted  as  a  necessary 
and  unobjectionable  complement  to  those  powers  that  are  in  fact  exercised 
by  the  national  government.  That  explains,  from  the  historical  standpoint, 

9Cf.  Bloch,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  1;  Dhonau,  May  L,  Decentralisation  in  Government 
Departments,  p.  5  ff.,  London:  Institute  of  Public  Administration,  1938;  Finer,  op.  at.  above 
in  note  1,  pp.  1281-1291.  For  German,  French,  and  British  experience,  see  also  Special  Com- 
mittee on  Comparative  Administration,  Committee  on  Public  Administration,  Social  Science 
Research  Council,  Memorandum  on  Regional  Codrdination,  pp.  13-19,  26-43,  Washington, 
March,  1943. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  267 

why  the  bulk  of  these  field  services  evolved  for  such  functions  as  carrying 
the  mail,  collecting  federal  taxes,  prosecuting  and  trying  legal  cases  under 
federal  law,  protecting  the  frontiers,  and  building  and  repairing  the  ships 
of  the  Navy.  In  fact,  the  story  of  the  growth  of  the  federal  field  services 
in  this  country  parallels  almost  directly  that  of  the  expansion  of  functions 
of  the  national  government.  In  many  ways  the  most  interesting  phases  of 
field  administration  developed  only  after  the  federal  government  under- 
took important  and  varied  regulatory  responsibilities  and  adopted  spending 
programs  designed  to  equalize  and  support  with  national  resources  the 
social  and  economic  opportunities  of  the  citizens  of  the  several  states. 

A  case  in  point  is  the  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture.  Al- 
though established  in  1862,  the  early  concentration  of  this  department 
upon  research  and  reporting  meant  that  for  many  years  there  was  no  need 
for  a  large  staff,  either  in  Washington  or  in  the  field.  Even  in  1905,  all 
functions  could  be  performed  by  about  5,000  employees,  70  per  cent  of 
whom  were  stationed  in  the  field.  Only  two  of  the  department's  bureaus 
had  extensive  field  services.  Yet,  in  1939,  the  demands  of  regulatory,  pro- 
motional, and  research  functions  had  so  multiplied  that  the  employees 
of  the  department  numbered  82,000 — sixteen  times  the  figure  for  1905 — 
while  85  per  cent  of  this  total  number  were  in  the  field  service.  In  the 
period  since  1905,  field  employment  had  increased  both  absolutely  and  rela- 
tively, reflecting  the  growth  and  changing  nature  of  the  department's 
responsibilities.4 

Thus  expansion  of  the  service  and  regulatory  functions  of  government 
underlies  much  of  the  expansion  of  field  services.  Indeed,  the  very  fact  that 
national  policy  could  be  administered  in  the  field—away  from  Washington 
— undoubtedly  made  more  palatable  the  idea  of  federal  assumption  of  much 
policy-making  that  earlier  had  been  thought  to  belong  to  state  and  local 
governments.  Similarly,  state  assumption  of  local  functions  has  often  been 
followed  by  arrangements  for  having  these  functions  administered  either 
through  field  agents  of  the  state  government  or  through  local  governments 
themselves  serving  in  effect  as  arms  of  state  administration. 

Technological  Progress.  Particularly  in  the  fields  of  transportation  and 
communication,  technological  progress  has  played  an  important  role  in  the 
expansion  of  field  services.  Technology  converts  local  commerce  into  na- 
tional commerce,  and  so  both  furthers  the  shifting  of  regulatory  and  pn> 
motional  functions  to  the  national  government  and  necessitates  expansion 
of  the  government's  field  services.  It  also  affects  directly  the  ease  of  contact 
between  citizens  and  the  national  capital  and  between  field  agents  and  the 
central  government.  In  fact,  the  facility  with  which  Washington  officials 

4  Truman,  David  B.,  Admini$trative  Decentralization,  pp.  36-41,  Chicago:  University  of 
Chicago  Press,  1940.  For  an  account  of  the  growth  of  the  functions  of  the  Department  of 
Agriculture,  see  Gaus,  John  M.  and  Wolcott,  Leon  C.,  Public  Administration  and  the  United 
States  Department  of  Agriculture,  pp.  3-90,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1940. 


268  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

and  citizens  in  all  parts  of  the  country  can  directly  communicate  with  one 
another  even  relieves  some  of  the  pressure  for  establishment  and  expansion 
of  field  services.  Some  federal  agencies  either  rely  entirely  on  their  func- 
tional divisions  at  Washington  for  operating  their  programs  or  merely 
establish  regional  divisions  within  their  Washington  headquarters. 

Paralleling  this  easing  of  central  headquarters-citizen  contact,  however, 
is  the  strengthening  of  bonds  connecting  departmental  officials  with  their 
field  personnel.  Through  telephone,  telegraph,  and  teletype,  through  air  mail 
and  regular  mail,  and  through  air  and  train  travel,  field  agents  and  central 
headquarters  are  in  daily  contact.  In  practice,  this  encourages  the  expansion 
of  field  services,  for  central  officials  need  have  no  fear  of  losing  control 
by  setting  up  field  offices.5  By  the  very  fact  that  advances  in  communication 
and  transportation  remove  distance  as  a  barrier  to  central  control,  they  are 
centralizing  influences.  Yet,  at  the  same  time,  they  permit  creation  of  a 
field  structure  within  which  decentralization  of  authority  can  go  forward 
without  impairing  the  ultimate  responsibility  of  departmental  headquarters 
for  the  agency's  total  program  and  operations. 

Scope  of  Field  Organization.  The  most  perplexing  and  important  prob- 
lems of  field  organization  in  this  country  arise  naturally  in  the  federal  gov- 
ernment, since  its  functions  extend  over  greater  territory  than  do  those  of 
the  states.  Nonetheless,  the  states  are  also  faced  by  the  necessity  for  field 
organization.  In  general,  the  states  have  lagged  considerably  behind  the 
federal  government  in  the  development  of  extensive  field  services.  This  has 
been  attributable  to  several  factors:  (1)  the  relatively  short  distances  between 
the  state  capital  and  the  other  communities  in  the  state,  with  the  result 
that  administration  directly  from  the  capital  was  in  most  cases  reasonably 
satisfactory;  (2)  the  extent  to  which  governmental  functions  were  per- 
formed by  counties,  towns,  and  special  districts;  and  (3)  the  less  satisfactory 
state  personnel  situation,  where  in  many  departments  employees  could  not 
be  spared  for  the  staffing  of  field  offices.6 

For  all  the  obviousness  of  the  need  for  extending  administration  through 
field  services,  it  is  generally  startling  to  look  at  the  statistics  that  demon- 
strate governmental  response  to  this  need.  In  the  federal  government,  for 
instance,  nine  employees  are  stationed  in  the  field  for  every  employee  sta- 
tioned in  Washington.  Of  the  total  of  almost  2.4  million  federal  em- 

5  Nonetheless,  there  is  some  indication  that  field  officials  in  the  Far  West,  being  visited 
less   frequently   by   Washington  officials  and   themselves  appearing  at  Washington  less  fre- 
quently than  eastern  field  officials,  have  a  greater  independence  of  central  direction. 

6  On  state  field  services  and  the  related  problem  of  administrative  areas,  see  Hansen, 
G.  H.,  A  Regional  Redistrictlng  Plan  for  the  State  of  Utah,  Provo:  Brigham  Young  University 
Press,  1937;  Menefee,  Selden  C.,  A  Plan  for  Regional  Administrative  Districts  in  the  State  of 
Washington,  Seattle:  University  of  Washington,  1935;  Uhl,  Raymond,  "Administrative  Regions 
in  Virginia,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1942,  Vol.  2,  pp.  50-63;  Hinderaker,  Ivan,  The 
Administrative  Districts  and  Field  Offices  of  the  Minnesota  State  Government t  Minneapolis:  Uni- 
versity of  Minneapolis  Press,  1943. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  269 

ployccs  in  April,  1946,  about  237,000  were  stationed  in  Washington  and 
2,163,000  in  the  field.  The  agencies  with  the  largest  number  of  field  em- 
ployees were,  in  the  order  of  size  of  field  personnel,  the  War,  Post  Office  and 
Navy  Departments,  all  with  fields  staffs  of  several  hundred  thousand; 
and,  with  less  than  150,000  employees  in  the  field,  the  Veterans  Administra- 
tion, the  Treasury  Department,  the  Department  of  Agriculture,  the  Interior 
Department,  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  and  the  War  Assets 
Administration.7 

2.  CENTRALIZATION  AND  DECENTRALIZATION 

Approach  to  Decentralization.  Since  field  organization  has  developed 
in  the  United  States  not  through  any  master  plan  but  in  response  to  the 
needs  of  individual  departments  and  bureaus,  naturally  there  is  diversity 
among  the  methods  of  field  administration.  Yet,  within  virtually  every 
agency  will  be  found  such  basic  problems  as  these:  thejaropcr  degree  of 
decentralization. of  authorit^^the  conflict  9f  interests  between  functional 
experts _at  headquarters  and  general  administrators  injhe  field;  the  basic 
need  for  intelligent  and  sympathetic  handling  of  relations  between  head- 
quarters and  the  field;  and  the  complexities  of  managing  a  field  structure 
having  two  or  even  three  successive  levels.  Each  of  these  intra-agency 
problems  will  be  considered  in  turn. 

The  question  of  the  degree  to  which  authority  should  be  delegated  to 
field  agents  requires  an  appreciation  of  the  character  of  field  organization  as 
a  facility  susceptible  of  different  uses.  It  is  an  efficient  tool  for  either  centrali- 
zation or  decentralization  of  authority.  Whether  or  not  decentralization — 
or  deconcentration — actually  characterizes  a  given  field  service  may  be 
discerned  from  observation  of  the  frequency  with  which  field  offices  must 
refer  matters  to  central  headquarters  for  decision;  the  number  and  specificity 
of  central  regulations  and  orders  governing  field  work;  the  provision  for 
citizen  appeal  to  headquarters  for  overruling  of  field  decisions;  the  degree 
to  which  all  of  the  agency's  field  activities  within  each  geographic  area  are 
directed  by  a  single  field  official;  the  volume  of  decisions  and  variety  of 
functions  of  the  agency;  and  the  caliber  of  field  officials.8  Since  authority 
stems  initially  from  the  center,  decentralization  requires  positive  actionJ 
Lack  dTfKis  sort  of  actionjresults  in  centralization.  For  such  representative 
functionTas"  tEosc In volvinglKe^gi-anNin^id  anchhc  agricultural  programs, 

7  United  States  Civil  Service  Commission,  Monthly  Report  of  Employment:  Executive 
Branch  oj  the  Federal  Government,  April,  1946.  It  should  be  noted  that  during  World  War  II 
several  central  services  were  removed  from  the  congested  national  capital. 

$See  Truman,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  pp.  56-58,  189;  Dhonau,  op.  cit.  in  note  3,  p. 
16;  Ulienthal,  David  E.,  TVA:  Democracy  on  the  Marih,  p.  161,  New  York:  Harper,  1944. 


270  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

the  federal  government  has  generally  failed  to  delegate  broad  authority  to 
its  field  agents.9 

The  factors  that  usually  control  the  degree  to  which  an  agency  cen- 
tralizes or  decentralizes  its  authority  fall  under  four  broad  headings: 
(1)  the  factor  of  responsibility;  (2)  administrative  factors;  (3)  functional 
factors;  and  (4)  external  factors.10 

Factor  of  Responsibility.  The  principle  of  administrative  responsibility 
acts  as  a  general  deterrent  to  the  decentralization  of  administrative  author- 
ity. The  principle  itself  is  familiar.  Every  agency  head  in  the  federal  gov- 
ernment is  answerable  for  his  general  administrative  program  to  the  Presi- 
dent, Congress,  and  the  people.  He  is  responsible  to  central  budgetary, 
accounting,  auditing,  and  personnel  agencies  and  to  the  courts  for  the 
integrity  and  legality  of  his  agency's  operations.  He  can  also  be  pilloried 
at  any  time  by  the  press,  committees  of  Congress,  and  political  enemies 
for  right  or  wrong  decisions  made  by  him  or  his  subordinates,  however 
picayune  the  matter. 

As  a  result,  agencies  hesitate  to  delegate  broad  discretionary  authority 
to  field  officials,  who  are  thought  to  be  less  readily  controlled  than  officials 
regularly  stationed  at  the  capital.  The  effects  of  this  system  of  responsibility, 
though  well-nigh  universal,  are  more  acute  in  some  agencies  than  in 
others.  An  instance  is  the  Public  Works  Administration,  which,  because  it 
performed  an  activity  traditionally  open  to  the  dangers  of  corruption  and 
graft,  set  up  a  highly  centralized  organization.11 

Administrative  Factors.  \The  second  main  cluster  of  factors  influencing 
decentralization  is  administrative  in  character,  specifically:  age  of  the 
agency,  stability  of  its  policies  and  methods,  competence  of  its  field  person- 
nel, pressure  for  speed  and  economy,  and  administrative  sophistication.  The 
age  of  the  agency  is  basic  to  several  of  the  other  administrative  factors 
mentioned.  Time  is  required  for  a  new  agency  to  get  well  staffed  and 
organized  at  headquarters,  for  key  officials  to  get  used  to  working  together, 
and  for  an  esprit  de  corps  to  develop  that  will  support  high  morale  in  the 

0  See  Key,  V.  O.,  The  Administration  of  Federal  Grants  to  the  States,  p.  222,  Chicago: 
Public  Administration  Service,  1937;  Truman,  op.  at.  above  in  note  4,  p.  195;  Vieg,  John  A., 
"Working  Relationships  in  Governmental  Agricultural  Programs,"  Public  Administration  Review, 
1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  146.  Cf.  also  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  p.  100,  New  York:  Knopf, 
1945.  A  rough  grouping  of  centralized  and  decentralized  agencies  is  suggested  in  Fesler, 
James  W.,  "Federal  Use  of  Administrative  Areas,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of 
Political  and  Social  Science,  1940,  Vol.  207,  p.  114. 

10  The  itemization  and  discussion  of  individual  factors  here  presented  are  based  in  part 
upon  Gulick,  Luther,  "Notes  on  the  Theory  of  Organization,"  in  Gulick,  L.  and  Urwick,  L., 
eds.,  Papers  on  the  Science  of  Administration,  p.  29  ff.t  New  York:  Institute  of  Public  Ad- 
ministration,  1937;  Truman,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  17  ff.\  Wallace,  Schuyler,  Federal 
Departmentalization,  pp.  133-144,  New  York:    Columbia  University  Press,  1941;  Dhonau,  op. 
cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  13  ff.,  135;  and  Fesler,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  9,  p.  114. 

11  Sec  Williams,  J.  Kcrwin,  Grants-in-Aid  Under  the  Public  Works  Administration,  p.  99, 
New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1939. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  271 

field.  Organization  and  staffing  of  a  field  service,  and  delegation  of  author- 
ity to  it,  must  generally  await  the  clarification  of  organization  and  author- 
ity at  the  center.12  And  even  after  a  field  service  is  organized  and  staffed, 
time  must  often  be  allowed  for  the  field  service  to  prove  itself  worthy  of 
the  confidence  of  headquarters  officials — a  confidence  that  is  a  prerequisite 
of  willingness  to  decentralize. 

Stability  of  policies  and  methods  is  fundamental.  As  long  as  headquar- 
ters itself  is  in  a  ferment  over  the  policies  to  b^pursued  by  the  agency,  it 
is  idle  to  talk  of  decentralization.  In  some  instances,  furthermore,  it  is 
only  by  temporary  centralization  of  all  decisions  that  headquarters  can 
reach  the  point  of  establishing  a  pattern  of  policies  on  the  basis  of  which 
decentralization  can  then  go  forward.13  |  ^ 

'Agencies  differ  in  the  degree  to  which  they  can  crystallize  and  stabilize 
policies  and  methods.  May  L.  Dhonau  has  suggested  that  the  judicial  type 
of  administrative  work  can  be  decentralized  more  extensively  than  other 
types  of  activity.14  J  Examples  would  be  the  settlement  of  claims  to  unem- 
ployment insurance  benefits  and  veterans'  pensions.  For  the  great  mass  of 
such  cases  that  are  filed  by  citizens,  the  answer  is  provided  either  in  the 
statutes  and  regulations  or  in  precedents  established  at  headquarters  early 
in  the  agency's  life.  Only  the  unusual  cases  need  be  referred  to  head- 
quarters for  central  decision. 

^The  competence  of  field  personnel  is  a  third  administrative  factor  gov- 
erning readiness  to  decentralize.  At  the  heart  of  the  disinclination  to  dele- 
gate substantial  authority  lies  the  conviction  of  many  officials  that  only  they 
themselves  have  the  ability  tcTdo  the  job  as  well  as  it  should  be  done.  To 
dissuade  them  from  this  point  of  view  requires,  among  other  things,  a 
demonstration  that  others,  both  at  headquarters  and  in  the  field,  can  do 
important  parts  of  the  job  competently.  The  field  officials  must  have  the 
confidence,  not  only  of  the  top  executives  of  the  agency,  but  also  of  the 
functional  specialists  down  the  line.  The  fact  that  a  field  office  can  rarely 

12  In    the   Works   Progress   Administration,    however,   the   internal   organization  of  state 
offices  was  crystallized  well  ahead  of  clarification  of  Washington  organization.    Sec  Macmahon, 
Arthur  W.,  Millett,  John  D.  and  Ogden,  Gladys,  The  Administration  of  Federal  Work  Relief, 
p.  208  ff.,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1941. 

13  An   instance   is   provided   by   the   Forest   Service's   centralization   of   certain   phases  of 
recreational  use  of  national  forests  until  new  policies  and  standards  could  be  developed.    See 
Loveridgc,  Earl  W.  and  Keplingcr,  Peter,  "Washington-Field  Relationships  in  the  Forest  Serv- 
ice," in  the  symposium  entitled  Washington-Field  Relationships  in  the  Federal  Service,  p.  33, 
Washington:  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  Graduate  School,  1942. 

14  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  135.  If  central  instructions  are  too  precise,  of  course,  no  true 
decentralization  could  ensue,  since  there  would  be  no  significant  discretion  to  be  exercised  in 
the  field  despite  the  volume  of  transactions  conducted  there.    For  the  contrast  presented  in 
the  inability  of  the  Office  of  Production  Management  to  decentralize,  see  Carey,  William  D., 
"Central -Field   Relationships  in   the  War  Production   Board,"  Public  Administration  Review, 
1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  35.   On  all  the  administrative  factors  of  decentralization  this  article  offers  a 
valuable  case  study. 


272  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

demonstrate  as  much  technical  competence  as  the  specialized  divisions  at  the 
agency's  headquarters  is  a  chief  deterrent  to  decentralization.15  ' 

An  illustration  of  the  interrelationships  of  such  factors  as  responsibility, 
age  of  agency,  stability  of  policies  and  methods,  and  competence  of  field 
personnel  is  afforded  by  the  Public  Works  Administration.  After  two  years 
of  centralized  administration — imposed  in  part,  as  we  noted,  because  of 
fear  of  graft  and  consequent  exposure  to  political  repercussions — the  agency 
decentralized  the  settlement  of  many  problems.  This  was  practicable,  in  the 
opinion  of  top  Washington  officials,  because  legal,  engineering,  and  financial 
examiners  with  experience  in  the  central  office  could  be  stationed  in  the 
field  offices,  where  their  analyses  and  action  on  project  applications  would  be 
both  competent  and  in  conformity  with  uniform  national  standards.16 

I/Problems  of  decentralization  are  complicated  by  a  fourth  administrative 
factor,  the  need  for  speed  and  economy  in  administrative  operations,  both 
to  satisfy  citizens  as  clients  of  the  agency  and  to  meet  budgetary  and  effi- 
ciency goals  of  the  agency  itself.  \  The  Disbursement  Division  of  the  Treas- 
ury Department,  for  example,  decentralized  its  certification  and  payment  of 
field  payrolls  of  most  federal  agencies  and,  during  the  depression  of  the 
1930's,  its  payment  of  relief  checks.  This  was  done  in  order  to  relieve  the 
Washington  office  of  the  heavy  administrative  burden  and  accelerate  the 
discharge  of  the  government's  financial  obligations,  thus  providing  speedier 
service  for  those  to  whom  the  federal  government  owed  money.17 

\Many  other  agencies  have  realized  that  officials  stationed  permanently 
in  particular  regions  with  authority  to  take  action  on  behalf  of  the  agency 
will  generally  have  lower  travel  and  communication  costs  than  headquarters 
officials  in  a  highly  centralized  organization.  Their  space  costs  may  be  lower 
than  those  in  the  crowded  capital.  Citizens  will  generally  appreciate  the 
opportunity  to  deal  with  a  near-by  official  rather  than  with  a  central  bureau 
that  can  be  visited  only  at  considerable  personal  expense.  <J- 

Administrative  sophistication,  particularly  with  regard  to  management 
of  a  field  service,  is  a  final  factor  influencing  decentralization.  Age  is,  of 
course,  a  contributing  element,  for — as  has  been  pointed  out — an  agency 
must  often  develop  its  principles  of  field  administration  in  an  experimental 
fashion  and  then  wait  for  their  crystallization  as  a  condition  to  sound 
understanding  of  both  subject  matter  and  administrative  problems  by  cen- 
tral and  field  personnel.  This  requires  time,  but  it  also  requires  a  highly 
intelligent  and  constructive  approach  by  all  key  officials.  A  professional 
approach  is  needed  to  such  questions  as  the  relative  values  of  centralization 
and  decentralization,  the  respective  roles  of  functional  experts  and  general 
administrators,  the  techniques  for  breaking  down  barriers  to  mutual  col- 
laboration between  central  headquarters  and  the  field  service,  and  the  appro- 

15  Sec  Carey,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  14,  p.  35. 

wSee  Williams,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  11,  p.  93;  Key,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  9,  p.  226. 

1*  Sec  Truman,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  29  ff. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  273 

priate  distribution  of  functions  and  authority  in  a  two-tier  or  three-tier 
field  organization.  Given  a  mature  approach,  an  agency  may  overcome 
many  of  the  apparent  obstacles  to  decentralization.  I 

Functional  Factors.  While  factors  of  responsibility  and  administration 
set  limits  to  the  feasibility  of  centralization  and  decentralization  for  indi- 
vidual departments,  the  most  marked  variations  among  governmental  agen- 
cies result  from  the  third  major  group  of  factors — those  concerned  with 
functions.  Here  the  factors  involve  answers  to  such  questions  as  these: 
How  great  a  variety  of  distinct  functions  does  the  agency  have?  How 
essential  is  technical  specialization  in  the  agency's  work  ?  Does  the  function 
require  national  uniformity  or  diversity  among  regions  and  localities? 

The  variety  of  functions  an  agency  performs  may  affect  its  readiness  to 
decentralize  operations.  (\n  agency  with  a  single  function  has  a  relatively  ' 
simple  problem  of  analysis  and  decision  in  order  to  determine  the  appro- 
priate degree  of  decentralization.  But  if  an  agency  performs  a  variety  of 
functions,  each  of  its  central  divisions  may  insist  on  a  separate  set  of  field 
offices  and  districts,  may  have  quite  contradictory  views  on  the  urgency 
or  the  extent  of  decentralization,  and  may  violently  oppose  control  of  its 
field  agents  by  a  field  official  representing  the  department  head  or  his  chief 
of  field  operations.! 

/  Reconciliation  of  these  different  viewpoints  may  be  impossible,  with  the 
result  that  either  no  decentralization  occurs  or  each  division  decentralizes 
as  it  chooses.  In  the  latter  event,  the  very  failure  to  get  agreement  on  an 
integrated  field  service  for  the  whole  department  may  retard  the  process 
of  decentralization^  The  department  head,  with  full  coordinative  author- 
ity over  officials  in  Washington  but  no  coordinative  machinery  in  the  field, 
may  very  well  fear  the  possibility  of  inefficiency,  duplication,  or  direct 
conflict  if  division  heads  delegate  a  large  degree  of  authority  to  their  field 
representatives.  It  is  also  true  that  in  cases  where  two  or  three  divisions 
need  to  reach  joint  decisions,  the  level  in  the  hierarchy  of  all  three  where 
the  decisions  will  be  ma'de  will  be  dictated  by  the  structure  of  the  least 
decentralized  division.  \  Consequently,  one  or  more  divisions  will  always 
act  as  "drags"  on  the  decentralization  of  other  divisions  in  a  department 
performing  a  variety  of  functions.| 

fin  some  agencies  there  is  a  pressing  need  for  technical  specialization. 
This,  particularly  in  a  small  agency,  usually  handicaps  attempts  to  decen- 
tralize the  work,  as  a  simple  comparison  will  make  clearf  If  for  a  certain 
purpose  an  agency  is  allowed  to  have  a  payroll  of  fifty  employees,  it  is  able 
to  concentrate  the  fifty  positions  in  a  central  staff  within  which  there  can 
be  both  general  administrators  and  groups  of  specialists  such  as  engineers, 
chemists,  and  budget  and  personnel  experts.  Or  it  may  want  to  open  per- 
haps forty  district  offices  in  the  field  and  assign  to  each  office  one  employee 
representing  the  whole  agency  in  all  of  its  specialized  aspects,  leaving  only 
ten  at  headquarters.  This  means  that  both  at  headquarters  and  in  the 


274  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

field  practically  all  positions  will  have  to  be  filled  by  employees  who  are 
not  trained  for  any  of  the  specialities  that  could  contribute  materially  to 
an  intelligent  job  of  administration. 

Ready  examples  from  recent  experience  are  afforded  by  the  Office  of 
Price  Administration  and  the  War  Production  Board.  At  Washington, 
each  agency  had  an  expert  on  almost  every  industry  and  commodity  in  the 
United  States.  But  to  duplicate  this  range  of  expertness  in  field  offices  was 
out  of  the  question.  It  is  a  general  rule  that  no  agency  has  in  each  of  its 
field  offices  as  great  a  range  of  specialization  as  is  represented  in  its  head- 
quarters staff.  This  necessarily  acts  as  a  bar  to  decentralization  by  agencies 
requiring  the  services  of  technical  personnel  in  reaching  most  of  their 
decisions. 

Variety  of  functions  and  need  for  technical  specialization  are  comple- 
mented by  a  third  functional  factor — the  degree  of  need  for  national  uni- 
formity as  contrasted  with  the  need  for  regional  and  local  variation.  This 
factor  goes  to  the  heart  of  differing  philosophies  of  government.  It  also 
raises  the  difficult  problem  of  how  to  measure  the  relative  efficiency  of  dif- 
fering administrative  techniques.  Thus  it  is  perhaps  both  the  most  basic 
and  the  least  tangible  of  all  the  factors  bearing  on  decentralization.  The 
fact  that  a  function  is  within  the  legal  jurisdiction  of  a  central  government 
does  not  mean  that  its  administration  cannot  be  decentralized.  Often  func- 
tions are  shifted  to  the  central  government  because  financial  or  personnel 
resources  are  greater  there  than  at  lower  governmental  levels;  because  policy 
formulation  needs  to  be  centralized;  or  because  the  central  government 
must  be  looked  to  for  assumption  of  ultimate  administrative  responsibility 
on  the  highest  level.  However,  unless  there  are  affirmative  reasons  for 
absolute  uniformity  in  detailed  operations  as  well  as  in  general  decisions 
of  the  agency,  authority  can  generally  be  decentralized  to  field  agents. 

The  most  obvious  need  for  diversity  in  administration  of  a  function 
arises  in  agencies  affected  by  differences  in  the  physical  characteristics  of 
the  various  parts  of  the  country.  Agricultural,  forest,  and  water-resource 
activities  are  examples.  On  the  other  hand, (the  principal  drive  toward 
centralization  comes  from  insistence  that  when  privileges  and  penalties  are 
being  dispensed  or  rights  determined,  equity  requires  an  identical  adminis- 
trative decision  in  every  identical  set  of  circumstances,  whether  the  case 
arises  in  Oregon,  Louisiana,  or  Maine.  Since  administrative  decisions  often 
involve  general  elements  of  judgment,  this  degree  of  uniformity  cannot  be 
assured  under  a  decentralized  system  permitting  each  field  igent  to  reach 
independent  conclusions  on  the  cases  arising  in  his  district?  Examples  of 
functions  demanding  uniformity  on  a  national  basis  are  the  administrative 
adjudication  of  veterans'  claims  for  compensation,  the  review  of  tax  returns, 
and  the  determination  of  the  relative  importance  of  various  products  in  the 
war  procurement  program.  ^s 

Externtd  Factors.  A  final  group  of  factors  bearing  on  the  centralization- 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  275 

decentralization  controversy  still  calls  for  discussion.  It  concerns  the  need 
for  an  agency  to  look  beyond  its  own  internal  operations  to  external  prob- 
lems. The  most  important  are  the  necessities  for  bringing  the  citizen  into 
the  administrative  process,  collaborating  with  other  federal,  state,  and  local 
agencies,  and  adapting  field  activities  to  political  pressures. 

The  first  of  these  factors  may  be  referred  to  as  the  degree  of  need  for^ 
support,  participation,  and  representation  at  the  "grass  roots"  of  democracy  ,x 
If  support  of  a  large  number  of  citizens  is  requisite  to  successful  admin- 
istration— as  was  true  of  the  farm  production  program  and  wartime  ra- 
tioning and  conscription;  or  if  their  participation  is  needed  to  impart 
wisdom  to  the  local  decisions  mad^-again  a  factor  in  these  three  programs; 
or  if  national  policy-makers  at  Washington  need  vigorous  representation 
of  regional  points  of  view  so  as  to  avoid  development  of  unrealistic  and 
extravagantly  uniform  national  plans,  then  under  such  conditions  a  de- 
centralized organization  is  likely  to  develop.18 

The  degree  of  need  for  collaboration  with  other  federal,  state,  and  local 
agencies  is  a  second  external  factor  in  decentralization  decisions.  Other 
things  being  equal,  an  agency's  decisions  should  be  made  at  the  level  of 
authority  that  is  most  convenient  for  other  agencies  participating  in  the 
decision-making  process.  This  mean's  that  if  federal  agencies  A  and  B 
have  a  number  of  joint  activities,  their  regional  officials  must  have  reason^- 
ably  similar  grants  of  discretionary  authority.  It  means  further  that  if 
the  program  is  one  of  federal  aid  to  the  states,  the  federal  agency  admin- 
istering the  program  will  probably  need  to  establish  regional  or  state  offices 
that  have  the  staff  and  authority  to  consult  with  the  state  governments 
and  *  give  them  final  answers  on  many  important  questions.  Similarly, 
pressure  for  a  degree  of  decentralization  develops  when  an  agency's  field 
officials  are  invited  to  participate  in  a  regional  planning  commission  or  to 
collaborate  with  an  establishment  promoting  regional  development,  like  the 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority.  Nonetheless,  it  is  probably  true  that  the  need 
for  collaboration  with  other  agencies  and  groups  exerts  only  a  secondary 
influence  on  a  department's  determination  of  the  desirable  degree  of  de- 
centralization. 

Finally,  among  external  /  factors,  political  aspects  must  be  considered. 
Since  the  strength  of  our  political  parties  lies  in  their  state  and  local  or- 
ganizations, there  is  some  danger  that  field  officials  of  the  federal  govern- 
ment will  come  under  heavy  local  pressures  from  the  powers  that  be.  This 
is  the  case  especially  if  the  field  officials  have  a  large  degree  of  discretion 
in  such  matters  as  the  appointing  of  employees,  awarding  of  contracts,  and 
making  of  money  grants  or  loans  of  one  kind  or  another  to  individuals. 
The  problem  is  particularly  acute  if  patronage  governs  the  selection  of  key 
field  officials  such  as  state  administrators  of  federal  agencies.  Indeed,  it 

18  See  Lilicnthal,  op.  tit.  above  in  note  8,  pp.  156-161,  and,  regarding  agricultural  land-use 
planning  programs,  Vieg,  he.  «V.,above  in  note  9,  p.  146. 


276  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

has  been  pointed  out  that  in  the  Works  Progress  Administration  "there 
were  occasions  when  state  and  district  administrators  took  the  attitude  that 
their  primary  allegiance  was  to  the  local  political  interest  that  had  obtained 
their  appointments  rather  than  to  WPA  headquarters  in  Washington."19 

Generally,  field  work  is  more  susceptible  to  political  inroads  than  de- 
partmental work  in  Washington.  Able  agency  heads  consequently  may 
shy  away  from  extensive  decentralization,  lest  they  be  forced  to  appoint  a 
large  number  of  politically  sponsored  employees.  By  the  same  token,  an 
able  Washington  staff  saddled  with  a  political  field  staff  may  be  anxious  to 
withhold  grants  of  real  power  to  the  field. 

In  sum,  then,  central  administrators  confronted  with  the  problem  of 
how  far  to  go  in  decentralizing  individual  activities  are  likely  to  be  influ- 
enced by  some  or  all  of  the  factors  here  reviewed. 

3.  FIELD-HEADQUARTERS  RELATIONS 

The  preceding  discussion  has  suggested  certain  fundamental  requisites 
for  the  maturing  of  field-headquarters  relations  in  an  agency.  It  may  be 
well  to  restate  them.  They  are:  the  adjustment  of  the  conflicting  interests 
of  functional  experts  and  general  administrators^  the  development  of 
methods  for  improving  mutual  field-headquarters  understanding  and  re- 
spect;*and  discovery  of  a  firm  formula  to  govern  relations  within  a  com- 
plex, multilevel  field  organization.  These  are  all  problems  that  arise  in 
every  field  service,  whether  authority  be  centralized  or  decentralized. 

Rivalry  of  Functional  Experts  and  General  Administrators.  The  most 
fundamental  of  the  three  problems  is  the  rivalry  of  functional  experts  and 
general  administrators.  Each  agency's  headquarters  office  is  subdivided 
into  specialized  units  dealing  with  different  programs,  techniques,  controls, 
and  services.  Some  of  them  are  so-called  line  or  operating  divisions,  re- 
sponsible for  important  segments  of  the  agency's  program.  Some  contribute 
special  skills,  such  as  engineering  and  statistics.  Others  exercise  manage- 
ment control  or  perform  managerial  services,  such  as  budgeting,  personnel, 
and  space  allocation.  But  each  of  the  main  divisions  is  responsible  to  the 
agency  head  or  to  one  of  his  chief  deputies.  Each  has  an  institutional  pride 
and  enthusiasm  for  its  own  part  of  the  total  program.  Each — as  can  be 
understood — would  dislike  to  see  important  phases  of  its  work  performed 
or  directed  by  other  divisions  and  officials.  In  fact,  to  such  extent  as  a 
division  cannot  actually  perform  or  direct  the  work  falling  within  its  sub- 
ject-matter specialty,  a  modification,  if  not  a  breakdown,  occurs  in  the 
system  of  responsibility. 

When  an  agency's  program  is  projected  into  the  field  there  arise  two 
basic  alternatives.  Each  division  may  be  allowed  to  set  up  its  own  field 
service  and  directly  control  the  performance  of  the  division's  functions  in 

wMacmahon,  Millctt  and  Ogden,  op.  tit.  above  in  note  12,  p.  279;  see  also  pp.  269-291. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  277 

the  field.  On  the  other  hand,  the  whole  agency  may  organize  an  integrated 
field  service,  with  each  regional,  state,  and  district  director  held  responsible 
for  all  agency  functions  performed  in  his  assigned  territory.  The  first 
alternative  has  the  defect  that  execution  of  the  agency  program  is  not  in- 
tegrated in  each  field  area.  The  second  alternative  has  the  defect  that 
functional  divisions  at  headquarters  have  no  direct  control  over  execution 
of  their  subject-matter  programs  in  the  field.  A  major  problem  of  ad- 
ministration is  to  avoid  the  impasse  between  the  apparently  irreconcilable 
positions  of  function  and  area,  of  functional  experts  and  general  admin- 
istrators. 

The  solutions  found  to  this  dilemma  stem  in  considerable  measure  from 
the  character  of  headquarters  organization.  If  the  agency  head  is  weak, 
or  if  the  agency  is  a  mere  confederation  of  unrelated  functional  divisions 
with  no  really  joint  objective  or  program,  the  functional  point  of  view 
is  likely  to  prevail  over  the  agency-wide  point  of  view  in  field  organiza- 
tion. Many  a  federal  department  embraces  so  wide  a  range  of  function* 
and  includes  such  powerful  and  tradition-encrusted  bureaus  that  any  single 
department-wide  field  structure  seems  out  of  the  question.  Difficult  aj 
has  been  the  establishment  of  agency-wide  areal  coordination  by  the  Socia! 
Security  Board,20  the  task  of  overcoming  functional  pulls  in  such  quasi 
departments  as  the  Federal  Security  Agency,  of  which  the  Social  Securitj 
Board  has  been  but  one  of  a  number  of  constituent  parts,  is  clearly  almos 
impossible.21 

Sheer  size  of  the  administrative  task,  often  but  not  always  a  companioi 
of  multiplicity  of  autonomous  bureaus  and  distantly  related  functions,  ma] 
also  be  a  deterrent  to  real  agency-wide  field  coordination.  The  volume  o 
orders  and  informational  paper  that  would  have  to  flow  to  field  coordinator 
if  functional  lines  of  authority  were  suppressed  in  such  an  agency  as  th< 
United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  is  fearful  to  contemplate. 

In  general,  though,  it  may  be  concluded  that  the  ability  of  a  depart 
ment's  field  coordinators  to  integrate  its  functions  for  given  areas  of  th< 
country  will  depend  heavily  on  the  strength  of  the  department  head  vis-b-vi 
his  bureau  heads,  and  on  the  inherent  need  for  integration  of  departmenta 
functions  because  of  their  subservience  to  a  single  purpose. 

Lines  of  Command.  Establishment  of  an  integrated  field  service  b 
no  means  ends  the  problems  of  function  versus  area.  For  there  remains 
never-ending  tussle  over  the  extent  to  which  the  agency's  regional  dlrecto 
must  take  orders  from  functional  divisions  at  headquarters.  This  applie 
also  to  the  amount  of  direct  contact  that  will  be  permitted  between  region* 
functional  divisions  and  their  central  prototypes.  There  are  really  onl 

20  See  Mitchell,  W.  L.,  "Washijigton-Field  Relations  in  the  Society  Security  Board,"  i 
op.  ciV.aJjove  in  note  13,  p.  44. 

^fSee,  however,  Roseman,  Alvin,  "The  Regional  Coordination  of  Defense  Health  an 
Welfare  Services,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  pp.  432-440. 


278  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

two  choices,  because   complete   autonomy   for   the  regional  director   is 
unattainable. 

One  choice  is  to  require  that  all  programs  and  major  orders  dear 
through  the  administrative  hierarchy,  while  technical  advice  is  handled 
directly  between  central  functional  divisions  and  their  regional  counter- 
parts. On  main  instructions  to  the  field,  the  central  functional  divisions 
would  make  recommendations  to  the  agency  head  or  his  deputy.  The 
latter,  on  the  basis  of  these  recommendations,  would  transmit  to  his  re- 
gional directors  such  orders  as  he,  a  general  administrator  like  the  regional 
directors,  deemed  desirable.  The  regional  director  in  turn  would  see  that 
the  orders  were  executed  by  his  regional  functional  divisions.  In  this 
pattern,  the  functional  officials  are  subordinated  at  each  step  to  the  general 
administrators. 

The  alternative  method,  called  "dual  command,"  appears  at  first  glance 
to  be  almost  indistinguishable  from  the  relationship  just  described.  How- 
ever, the  difference  is  that  between  subordinating  functional  specialties  to 
general  administration  and  recognizing  "a  double  line  of  control."22  Under 
such  dual  command,  regional  functional  experts  must  look  for  orders  both 
to  the  regional  director  and  to  the  functional  divisions  at  headquarters. 

Again,  as  in  the  question  of  the  feasibility  of  decentralization,  no  single 
formula  will  fit  all  agencies.  Too  much  depends  on  the  unity  of  purpose 
of  the  particular  agency  and  the  consequent  need  for  integrating  all  of  its 
functions.23  A  great  deal  depends  also  on  the  effectiveness  with  which  the 
needed  integration  is  actually  achieved  by  a  strong  agency  head.  If  head- 
quarters is  simply  a  tent  under  which  autonomous  bureaus  are  gathered 
for  mere  appearance's  sake,  there  is  no  possibility  of  a  strong  regional 
director  being  able  to  challenge  the  flow  of  "technical" — as  distinguished 
from  "administrative" — commands. 

C  If  the  agency  really  has  a  single  purpose,  requiring  that  its  functions  be 
geared  together,  the  need  for  a  strong  hierarchy  of  general  administrators 
built  into  both  the  headquarters  and  field  organizations  is  great.  A  single- 
purpose  agency  has,  in  addition,  the  incidental  advantage  that  its  regional 
directors  can  be  men  and  women  with  some  specialized  training,  able  to 
command  respect  from  the  functional  divisions?/ On  the  other  hand,  a 
wide-ranging  agency  like  the  Social  Security  Board  must  choose  "gencral- 
ists"  whose  contributions  to  administration  the  functional  experts  tend  to 
underrate.24 

In  practice,  the  dynamism  of  functional  divisions  and  the  professional 
bond  between  the  staff  of  each  such  central  division  and  its  regional  coun- 
terpart weight  the  scales  against  the  general  administrators.  This  combina- 
tion of  influences  tends  to  reduce  regional  directors  to  mere  providers  of 

^Macmahon,  Millett  and  Ogden,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  12,  pp.  265-267. 

23  See  Stone,  Donald  C.,  "Washington-Field  Relationships,"  in  op.  cit.  in  note  13,  p.  16. 

24  See  Mitchell,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  20,  p.  43. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  279 

common  facilities  such  as  space,  stenographic  pools,  and  mail  routing; 
freely  available  speech-makers;  and  recorders  of  what  goes  on—  the  field 
"eyes  and  ears"  of  headquarters.  [The  centrifugal  force  of  the  functional 
divisions  has  been  so  strong  that*  the  administrative  problem  has  nearly 
always  been  how  to  strengthen  the  regional  director,  and  seldom  how  to 
increase  the  role  of  the  functional  divisions.25) 

Whatever  the  basic  formula  hammered  out  between  i 


generalists  and  functionalists  may  be,  an  agency  has  day-to-day  problems 
of  headquarters-field  relations,  most  of  which  revolve  about  four  issues: 
personnel  policies;  the  headquarters  office  of  field  operations;  communica- 
tions; and  control.  In  the  case  of  personnel  policies,  field  relations  are 
often  muddied  by  jealousy  over  relative  salaries..  In  the  Work  Projects 
Administration  in  March,  1937,  for  example,  the  average  annual  salary  for 
Washington  was  $2,251,  but  the  average  salaries  for  the  state  and  district 
offices  were  respectively  $1,633  and  $1,401.26 

A  regrettable  lack  of  mutual  understanding  also  develops  when  there 
is  no  exchange  of  personnel  between  headquarters  and  field  stations.  The 
Bridgeman  Committee  on  reform  of  the  British  postal  service  put  both  of 
these  problems  bluntly  when  it  recommended,  "As  a  rule  no  officer  should 
be  appointed  to  an  administrative  position  of  importance  at  Headquarters 
without  a  thorough  training  in,  and  experience  of,  work  in  the  Provinces. 
There  should  be  no  difference  in  status  between  the  administrative  Staff 
at  Headquarters  and  in  the  Provinces.'*27  The  free  movement  of  personnel, 
both  vertically  and  horizontally,  is  necessary  not  only  to  increase  awareness 
of  field  problems  at  headquarters  and  to  open  opportunities  of  promotion 
for  field  staff  members,  but  also  to  counteract  provincialism  within  field 
districts.28 

Transfer  of  field  personnel  among  districts  can  both  widen  opportunities^ 
for  promotion  and  overcome  provincialism.  However,  in  the  Social  Se- 
curity Board,  each  regional  office  having  a  vacancy  tended  to  resent  the 
passing  over  of  its  own  staff  members  in  favor  of  some  one  from  another 
region.29  The  national  movement  of  personnel  is  also  handicapped  by  the 
need  for  placating  sectional  prejudices  by  the  appointment  of  ^natiyes^  Jo 
rcgionalofficcs,  and  by  the  value  to  an  agency  of  regional  representatives 
wno^riTtlioroughly  acquainted  with  the  agency's  clients  in  the  region  and 

25  See  Great  Britain,  Citrine  Committee  on  Regional  Boards,  Report,  p.  7  ff.,  Cmd.  6360, 
London  1942;  Dhonau,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  95  ff.,  153;  Key,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  9, 
p.  219  ff.;  Williams,  op.  cif.  above  in  note  11,  p.  94;  Fesler,  James  W.,  "Areas  for  Industrial 
Mobilization,  1917-1941,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  V,  pp.  149-166. 

26  See  Macmahon,  Millett  and  Ogden,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  12,  p.  229. 

2T  Quoted  in  Dhonau,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  97;  for  Miss  Dhonau's  concurrence,  see 
p.  154.  For  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  experience,  see  Truman,  op.  cit.  above 
in  note  4,  p.  194. 

28  Such  provincialism  "is  one  of  the  most  frequent  causes  of  misunderstanding  or  friction 
in  central-field  relationships."   Loveridge  and  Keplinger,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  13,  p.  32. 

29  Sec  Mitchell,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  20,  p.  48. 


280  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

sensitive  to  the  more  subtle  regional  trends.80  A  fortunate  countervailing 
tendency  is  the  fear  of  an  agency,  such  as  the  Public  Works  Administration, 
that  a  field  administrator  might  favor,  or  be  accused  of  favoring,  his  own 
state  or  region.  The  solution  hit  upon  in  this  agency  was  "for  the  ad- 
ministrator to  be  chosen  from  outside  the  district  in  which  he  was  to 
serve,  despite  the  danger  that  he  might  be  unfamiliar  with  local  conditions 
and  unacceptable  to  the  local  officials  with  whom  he  should  work  haiy 
moniously."31 

Headquarters  Office  of  Field  Operations.  A  second  major  issue  of 
headquarters-field  relations  is  the  role  and  status  of  the  headquarters  office 
of  field  operations.  In  theory,  as  we  have  seen,  the  principle  of  the  single 
chain  of  command  requires  that  regional  directors  receive  all  important 
orders  from  the  agency  head,  not  from  the  functional  divisions.  Yet  the 
agency  head  rarely  can  give  personal  attention  to  each  of  these  orders. 
Hence  he  often  establishes  an  office  of  field  operations  through  which  all 
functional  and  other  orders  proposed  for  issuance  to  the  field  must  be 
cleared,  the  field  viewpoint  may  be  reflected  to  headquarters  for  staff 
discussions,  and  the  agency  head  can  maintain  administrative  supervision 
of  field  operations. 

The  dangers  inherent  in  this  solution  are  several.  The  office  of  field 
operations  may  become  procedure-minded  and  fail  to  develop  a  broad 
appreciation  of  the  total  agency  program.  It  may  lack  the  prestige  and 
broad-gauged  personnel  needed  for  effective  participation  in  policy  coun- 
cils at  headquarters.  It  may  overstep  its  authority  by  captiously  revising 
programs  that  have  been  developed  by  functional  divisions.  And,  by 
barring  direct  contact  between  regional  directors  and  headquarters  officials, 
it  may  depress  field  morale  and  undermine  central-field  understanding. 

As  the  Work  Projects  Administration  discovered,  there  is  in  a  sense 
no  distinguishable  division  of  activity  to  justify  the  label  of  field  relations. 
Instead,  jevery  division  at  headquarters  is  concerned  with  field  relations 
and  must  somehow  be  linked  with  the  other  divisions  in  a  collaborative 
endeavor  to  get  the  agency's  objectives  realized  through  the  field  serviofc 
One  of  the  most  promising  wartime  experiments  of  this  character  was  the 
Operations  Council  of  the  War  Production  Board.  It  brought  together 
regularly  the  operations  vice-chairman  of  WPB,  the  regional  directors,  the 
heads  of  functional  divisions,  and  the  head  of  the  office  of  field  operations. 
In  addition,  the  regional  directors  caucused  separately,  with  a  view  to 
pointing  up  issues  that  should  be  brought  to  the  attention  of  the  chairman 
of  WPB. 

.Problems  of  Communication.  This  suggests  the  third  problem  of  cen- 
tral-field relations — that  of  communication.  The  formal  pattern  for  com- 
munication from  headquarters  to  the  field  is  established  by  such  rules  as 

30  See  Key,  op.  at.  above  in  note  9,  p.  92,  106  ff. 
81  Williams,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  11,  p.  72. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  281 

"orders  must  flow  through  the  office  of  field  operations,"  and  "advice  may 
flow  directly  from  functional  divisions  at  headquarters  to  their  counter- 
parts in  the  field."  But  this  formalization  of  channels  by  no  means  meets 
fully  all  problems.  How  are  regional  administrators  to  keep  informed  of 
the  flow  of  technical  advice  to  their  subordinates?  How  can  field  officials 
be  given  adequate  understanding  of  the  total  program  of  the  agency? 
How  can  functional  divisions  be  prevented  from  dropping  "paratroops" 
into  regions  to  perform  special  brief  assignments — or  how  can  this  practice 
at  least  be  kept  from  undermining  the  regional  director's  responsibility  for 
all  agency  activities  in  the  region?  How  can  field  officials  be  apprised  of 
central  decisions  in  advance  of  their  appearance  under  headquarters  date- 
lines in  the  region's  newspapers?  How  can  headquarters  answers  given 
directly  to  officials  of  state  and  local  governments,  business  corporations, 
and  private  citizens,  be  kept  consistent  with  the  answers  of  regional  offices 
to  the  same  people?  And  how  can  headquarters  be  kept' informed  of -com- 
munications among  regional  offices  ?  In  addition,  there  is  tKe  important  and 
puzzling  question  of  the  volume  and  type  of  reports  that  field  officials 
must  file  centrally  to  keep  headquarters  informed  of  developments  all  over 
the  country  and  to  facilitate  effective  supervision  over  the  field  services. 

Despite  the  variety  and  difficulty  of  these  communication  problems,  the 
most  fundamental  question  is  probably  that  of  how  field  officials  can  be 
brought  to  play  a  constructive 'part  in  the  formulation  of  agency  policies 
and  procedures.  Few  able  officials  are  content  to  be  mere  executors  of 
central  instructions,  or  mere  pedestrian  writers  of  weekly  reports  "to  keep 
headquarters  informed."  As  Donald  C.  Stone  says,  "Policy,  programs, 
and  procedures  must  be  developed  and  constantly  revalued  in  terms  of 
operating  and  administrative  experience,  and,  with  a  few  exceptions,  this 
experience  is  taking  place  in  the  field."^/Two  things  are  called  for:  the 
consultation  of  field  officials  by  headquarters  in  the  development  of  national 
policies;  and  the  devolution  of  planning  authority/so  that,  as  in  the  Forest 
Service,  officials  at  each  administrative  level — national,  regional,  and  sub- 
regional — will  have  planning  tasks  appropriate  to  their  assigned  areas  and 
interlocked  with  the  plans  of  the  other  levels.33 

Controls  Over  Field  Organization.  The  need  for  rigid  headquarters 
controls  may  be  in  roughly  inverse  ratio  to  the  success  with  which  com- 
munication problems  are  solved  and  real  understanding  is  developed  be- 
tween headquarters  and  the  field.34  Nevertheless,  ^communication  is  never 
so  perfect  as  to  obviate  the  need  for  all  controls.  ( 

The  three  principal  methods  of  headquarters  control  are  advance  review, 

^2  Lor.  tit.  above  in  note  23,  p.  18. 

88  Sec  Loveridge  and  Keplinger,  loc.  at.  above  in  note  13,  p.  31. 

84  See  Truman,  David  B.,  "Headquarters  and  the  Field/'  Public  Administration  Review 
1942,  Vol.  2,  p.  359.  C/.  also  Carey,  William  D.,  "Control  and  Supervision  of  Field  Offices,' 
jfttt,  1946,  Vol.  6,  pp.  20-24. 


282  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

g,  and  inspection.  Advance  review  interferes  to  some  degree  with 


ll-nedged  decentralization,  for  it  means  the  referral  of  matters  to  headj 
quarters  for  decision.    An  example  would  be  the  requirement  that  eacl 
field  office  do  all  the  investigation  of  a  case  arising  in  its  area,  but  refe 
the  case,  with  its  recommendation  and  supporting  data,  to  headquarter 
for  the  actual  decision.    Differing  only  in  degree  is  the  initial  decisioi 
of  a  case  in  the  field,  with  the  citizen  having  a  ready  course  of  appeal  t< 
headquarters.  On  the  management  side,  advance  review  can  mean  control 
of  budgets,  personnel  transactions,  space  allocation,  and  other  managerial 
facilities. 

Reporting,  which  has  aptly  been  termed  a  device  of  "remote  control," 
places  reliance  on  statistical  and  narrative  accounts  submitted  by  field 
officials  to  headquarters.  Through  these  reports,  comparisons  can  be  made 
among  field  offices  to  check  on  efficiency  and  to  spot  successful  experi- 
ments deserving  of  application  by  all  field  offices.  Headquarters  can  also 
set  field  offices  straight  on  any  problems  raised  in  their  reports,  and  direct 
them  to  change  unsatisfactory  practices. 

A  chief  problem  in  reporting  as  a  tool  of  control  is  that  its  utility 
depends  so  much  on  the  very  officials  over  whom  control  is  being  attempted. 
Few  of  them  will  consciously  report  adversely  on  their  own  operations. 
Consequently,  the  device  of  "remote  control"  is  most  appropriate  for  those 
agencies  whose  field  work  can  be  meaningfully  measured  in  quantitative 
terms35  and  for  whom,  therefore,  the  form  and  content  of  reports  can  be 
prescribed  beyond  any  ability  of  the  field  official  to  escape  self-revelation 
of  his  errors.  Even  in  such  agencies  there  are  instances,  like  the  Work 
Projects  Administration,  where  politically  appointed  field  administrators 
are  so  distrusted  that  statistical  reporting  is  set  up  outside  their  control, 
pending  at  least  the  maturing  of  reporting  methods  to  the  foolproof  stage.36 

Inspection  is  essential  to  effective  central  control,  yet  it  is  a  constant 
irritant  to  field  officials.  Unless  they  are  unusually  skillful,  inspectors  must 
either  be  superficial  and  ineffective  or  be  "snoopers"  trying  to  get  under 
surface  appearances  and  consequently  undermining  the  field  staff's  feeling 
that  their  office  chief  has  the  full  confidence  of  headquarters.  A  field 
administrator  tolerates  with  some  distaste  the  brief  visits  of  central  agents 
who  subsequently  write  reports  and  recommendations  on  matters  he  feels 
would  require  them  months  or  years  to  master. 

One  device  for  preserving  the  field  official's  dignity  is  to  let  him  see  the 
central  inspector's  report  and  submit  his  own  comments  to  accompany  it. 
Another,  and  perhaps  the  most  important,  is  for  the  inspector  to  be  more 
a  counselor  and  less  a  reporter  or  examiner  of  formal  obedience  to  pro- 
cedural instructions.  As  a  counselor  he  may  ingratiate  himself  with  the 
field  officials  and  help  them  with  ideas  on  how  to  do  a  better  job,  prefer- 

85  See  Dhonau,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  p.  153. 

86  See  Macmahon,  Millett  and  Ogdcn,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  12,  pp.  238-240. 


FIElJD  ORGANIZATION  283 

ably  letting  the  ideas  appear  to  originate  with  the  field  men  themselves. 
The  spirit  animating  inspection  work  will  necessarily  depend  on  the  level 
of  competence  in  the  field  service.  Unless  the  field  employees  are  reason- 
ably able,  control,  rather  than  stimulation  and  encouragement,  will  be  the 
motif  of  inspection. 

Problems  of  Multilevel  Field  Organization.  Somewhat  distinctive 
problems  of  central-field  relations  arise  in  the  multilevel  field  organiza- 
tion. In  many  agencies,  the  typical  field  structure  involves  regional  offices 
and  state  or  district  offices,  and,  in  some  instances,  a  still  lower  level.  Such 
a  pattern  develops  especially  among  agencies  having  a  large  clientele  and  a 
large  volume  of  field  work,  with  the  consequent  necessity  for  local  offices 
within  easy  travel  distance  of  their  clients.  This  may  mean  up  to  hundreds 
of  local  offices.  Yet,  considering  the  span  of  control,  it  is  impossible  for 
a  headquarters  director  of  field  operations  to  supervise  directly  so  many 
chiefs  of  local  offices.  He  may  meet  the  problem  by  providing  himself 
with  a  large  staff  of  assistants  in  his  central  office.  Or,  as  is  more  customary, 
he  may  establish,  say,  a  dozen  regional  offices  as  an  intermediate  level 
between  himself  and  the  local  offices. 

The  problems  coming  up  in  such  a  multilevel  field  structure  are  not 
easily  solved.  If  the  regional  office  is  powerful  and  if  devolution  of  au- 
thority to  it  is  the  rule,  headquarters  will  be  in  inadequate  contact  with 
the  "firing  line"  of  local  offices.  As  a  result,  headquarters  will  tend  to 
"that  remoteness  in  high  places  and  divorce  between  theory  and  practice 
which  it  is  the  very  aim  of  decentralization  to  avoid."37  Similarly,  strict 
hierarchical  principles  would  demand  that  the  regional  office  have  exclu- 
sive inspectional  authority  over  local  offices.  The  consequence  would  be 
that  the  central  inspectional  control — save  over  regional  offices — would 
tend  to  atrophy.  Of  course,  it  would  be  dangerous  to  separate  what  a 
French  scholar,  Hauriou,  has  called  the  "noncombatants"  at  headquarters 
from  the  "combatants"  in  the  local  offices.  Despite  theory,  this  threat  has 
led  to  frequent  deliberate  by-passing  of  the  regional  offices.  If,  on  the 
other  hand,  regional  offices  are  not  powerful  and  are  inadequately  staffed| 
with  experts,  they  become  merely  delay  points  in  the  transmission  of 
ters  from  the  local  offices  to  headquarters,  which  alone  has  functional 
pertness. 

There  is  often  dispute  as  to  whether  headquarters  or  the  regional  office 
should  determine  the  location  and  jurisdiction  of  local  offices  and  appoint 
their  chiefs.  It  is  certainly  true  that  regional  offices,  in  working  out  their 
supervisory  relations  to  local  offices,  confront  many  of  the  problems  of 
internal  organization  that  are  prevalent  at  headquarters,  such  as  the  con- 
flict of  interest  between  functional  experts  and  general  administrators,  and 

87  Dhonau,  op.  «>.  above  in  note  3,  p.  134. 


284  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

the  question  of  the  desirability  of  a  regional  division  of  field  relations.38 

4.  INTERAGENCY  COORDINATION  IN  THE  FIELD 

Divergencies  in  Field  Organization.  In  the  United  States,  as  we  have 
observed  earlier,  each  bureau  and  agency  having  field  functions  has  de- 
veloped its  own  field  service.  As  a  result,  the  federal  government  has  no 
integrated  field  organization  such  as  those  established  by  governments  of 
continental  Europe.  Instead,  it  has  well  over  a  hundred  separate  field  serv- 
ices. For  each  of  these,  the  sponsoring  agency  locates  field  offices,  delineates 
regional  boundaries,  and  determines  the  desirable  degree  of  decentralization 
with  primary  reference  to  the  administrative  and  functional  requirements  of 
its  own  operations,  but  with  slight  reference  to  the  broader  interests  of  the 
whole  government. 

To  some  extent,  the  diversity  in  field  organization  is  due  to  minor  con- 
siderations of  administrative  or  personal  convenience;  to  political  pressures 
affecting  the  selection  of  field  centers;  and  to  lack  of  imagination  in  appre- 
ciating the  need  for  decentralization  and  the  desirability  of  interagency 
collaboration. 

The  importance  of  these  influences  can  be  exaggerated,  however.  There 
are  sound  grounds  for  handling  field  operations  in  connection  with  agri- 
cultural production  differently  from  field  operations  in  taking  the  census, 
inspecting  steamboats,  rationing  food,  settling  labor  disputes,  or  supervising 
Indian  reservations.  Since  the  clustering  and  the  nature  of  the  phenomena 
with  which  government  is  concerned  vary,  diversity  among  the  field  or- 
ganizations for  dealing  with  these  phenomena  is  natural.  The  factors  to 
be  considered  in  laying  out  regional  boundaries,  locating  field  offices,  and 
decentralizing  authority  can  be  enumerated  without  too  much  difficulty. 
Yet  the  relative  weight  of  each  factor  will  vary  agency  by  agency  and 
function  by  function,  with  the  result  that  even  a  consciously  logical 
approach  to  field  organization  will  lead  to  differing  arrangements.30 

38  Cf.  Macmahon,  Millett  and  Ogdcn,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  12,  pp.  200-207,  233-236; 
Hedge,  A.  M.  and  Benson,  George  C.  S.,  "Supervision  and  Inspection  of  Local  Projects  by 
Regional  Offices,"  No.  43  in  Committee  on  Public  Administration,  Social  Science  Research 
Council,  Case  Reports  in  Public  Administration,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1941; 
Click,  Philip  M.  and  Barrows,  Leland,  "Administrative  Reorganization  of  a  Federal  Agency-. 
Elimination  of  Regional  Offices,"  No.  87  in  ibid.,  1944;  Goodnck,  M.  George,  "WPB  De- 
centralization Within  the  Chicago  Region,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp. 
208-219. 

"For  descriptive  lists,  maps,  and  analyses  of  federal  administrative  regions  and  head- 
quarters, see  National  Resources  Committee,  Regional  Factors  in  National  Planning  and  De- 
velopment, pp.  71-82,  203-233,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1935;  Fcslcr,  James 
W.,  "Federal  Administrative  Regions,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1936,  Vol.  30, 
pp.  257-268;  Legislative  Reference  Service,  Library  of  Congress,  Federal  Field  Offices,  pp. 
55-58,  Senate  Doc.  No.  22,  78th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  1943;  Division  of  Public  Inquiries,  Office 
of  War  Information,  Regional  Offices  of  Federal  Departments  and  Agencies,  Washington,  1945. 

For  factors  relevant  to  agency  choice  of  regional  boundaries  and  headquarters,  see  Legis- 
lative Reference  Service,  Library  of  Congress,  op.  cit.\  Fesler,  James  W.,  "Criteria  for  Ad- 
ministrative Regions,"  Social  Forces,  1943,  Vol.  22,  pp.  26-32. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  285 

Granting  the  need  for  diversity  among  field  organizations,  it  can  be 
pressed  too  far.  In  its  extreme  version,  it  would  call  for  a  distinctive  field 
service  for  every  function  and  subfunction  of  every  agency,  thus  destroy- 
ing the  idea  of  an  integrated  field  service,  even  for  an  agency  with  a  single 
major  purpose.  And  in  cases  where  the  need  for  diversity  is  genuine,  we 
must  still  accommodate  in  some  fashion  the  necessity  for  interagency  co- 
ordination in  the  field.  Attempts  to  meet  this  necessity  have  revolved 
about  four  problems:  increased  uniformity  in  the  location  of  regional 
boundaries  and  field  offices;  joint  action  to  effect  economies  in  institutional 
services;  coordination  in  the  execution  of  programs;  and  coordination  in 
the  planning  of  programs. 

Emerging  Uniformities.  One  of  the  ideas  most  appealing  to  the  lay- 
man is  that  of  bringing  order  out  of  the  supposed  chaos  of  regional  boun- 
daries and  field  offices.  Its  popularity  can  be  constructively  used  to  bring 
field-service  geography  into  greater  similarity  of  pattern  in  the  absence  of 
compelling  functional  or  administrative  grounds  for  diversity.  On  the 
other  hand,  little  likelihood  exists  of  any  agreement  upon  a  single  master 
scheme  of  regional  boundaries  to  which  all  agencies  would  have  to  con- 
form.40 

Identity  of  regional  office  locations  is  an  ideal  that  can  be  more  closely 
approximated  than  identity  of  regional  boundaries.  We  observe  a  definite 
preference  among  the  thirty-three  largest  federal  agencies  for  certain 
strategically  located  cities.  Leading  in  preference  are  Chicago,  New  York, 
San  Francisco,  Atlanta,  Boston,  Kansas  City,  Dallas,  Cleveland,  Philadel- 
phia, and  Denver.41  A  report  of  the  National  Resources  Committee 
arrived  at  the  following  list  of  cities  as  the  ideal  centers  for  regional  plan- 
ning: Boston,  New  York,  Knoxville,  Atlanta,  New  Orleans,  Portland,  San 
Francisco,  and  Denver.42  Some  large  departments,  even  though  they  are 
not  planning  an  early  establishment  of  integrated  field  services  of  a  de- 
partment-wide character,  are  making  conscious  efforts  to  get  bureau  field 
offices  located  in  common  cities,  and,  if  possible,  in  common  buildings. 

The  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture,  for  instance,  has  made 
some  progress  in  this  direction,  even  looking  beyond  field  centers  to  the 
establishment  of  common  regional  boundaries  for  its  bureaus.  However, 
political  considerations  have  retarded  the  program.43  Apparently  the  early 
efforts  have  been  directed  toward  building  up  strong  nuclei  at  Philadelphia, 

40  C/.    Fesler,    James    W.,   "Standardization   of   Federal    Administrative  Regions,"   Social 
Forces,  1936,  Vol.  15,  pp.  76-81. 

41  See  Latham,  Earl,  "Executive  Management  and  the  Federal  Field  Service,"  Public  Ad- 
ministration Review,   1945,  Vol.  5,  p.   16.    For  a  slightly  different  list  of  frequently  chosen 
field  centers,  based  on  all  regionalizing  agencies  for  1934-35,  see  Fesler,  "Federal  Adminis- 
trative Regions,"  he.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  p.  265  ff.,  and  National  Resources  Committee,  op.  cit. 
in  note  39,  p.  30,  72  ff. 

42  See  op.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  p.  195. 

48  See  Appleby,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  9,  p.  99. 


286  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

Milwaukee,  Lincoln,  Neb.,  and  San  Francisco.  A  final  indication  of  cities 
likely  to  emerge  as  regional  centers  is  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget's  selection  of 
Dallas,  San  Francisco,  Chicago  and  Denver,  as  the  location  of  its  new  field 
offices.44 

Pooling  of  Field  Resources.  Whatever  the  ultimate  compromise  be- 
tween uniformity  and  diversity  in  regional  boundaries  and  headquarters 
will  be,  there  will  continue,  as  in  the  past,  to  be  need  for  interagency  co- 
ordination in  the  field.  Historically,  such  coordination  was  earliest  devel- 
oped in  attempts  at  economies  in  such  common  institutional  services  as 
office  and  storage  space,  trucking  facilities,  equipment,  personnel,  and  purJ 
chasing.  This  was  the  working  focus  of  the  area  coordinators  of  the 
Federal  Coordinating  Service  and  the  federal  business  associations  from  1921 
to  1933  45 

The  most  promising  recent  developments  in  federal  administration 
toward  interagency  pooling  of  institutional  resources  in  each  major  area  and 
city  are  two.  One  is  the  decentralization  effected  within  certain  institutional 
service  agencies,  such  as  the  Civil  Service  Commission  and  the  Disburse- 
ment Division  of  the  Treasury  Department.  The  other  is  the  establish- 
ment of  field  offices  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget.  The  Budget  Bureau, 
through  its  field  offices,  is  uniquely  equipped  to  draw  together  in  each 
area  the  institutional  service  agencies;  to  link  these  in  turn  closely  to  the 
operating  agencies;  and  to  bring  pressure  for  economies  that  can  result 
from  effective  handling  of  institutional  services. 

We  do  not  minimize  institutional  services  if  we  hold  that  if  interagency 
coordination  in  the  field  focuses  on  the  above  objectives  alone — which  was 
largely  true  throughout  the  1920's — vastly  more  important  problems  of 
administration  will  be  overlooked.  One  of  these  is  how  to  coordinate  the 
execution  of  the  programs  of  all  federal  agencies  in  any  particular  region. 
The  elements  basic  to  interagency  cooperation  in  the  field  have  been  iden- 
tified as:  familiarity  with  other  agencies'  work;  informal  acquaintance; 
physical  proximity;  a  specific  objective;  a  limited  number  of  participants; 
and  approximately  equal  status  of  the  participants.40 

The  first  two  elements — awareness  of  what  other  agencies  are  doing 
and  an  informal  acquaintance  with  their  officials  in  the  area — can  find 
recognition  in  part  through  luncheon  clubs,  such  as  the  surviving  federal 
business  associations,  the  USDA  Clubs  of  the  United  States  Department 

44  See  the  testimony  of  Budget  Director  Harold  D.  Smith,  Senate  Committee  on  Appro- 
priations, Hearings,  Independent  Offices  Appropriation  Bill  for  1945,  p.  231,  78th  Cong.,  2d 
Scss.,  Washington,  1944. 

48  The  field  work  of  the  Federal  Coordinating  Service  is  critically  reviewed  in  Fesler, 
James  W.,  "Executive  Management  and  the  Federal  Field  Service,"  in  President's  Committee  on 
Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Studies t  pp.  279-282,  Washington:  Gov- 
ernment Printing  Office,  1937. 

43  £/.  Fesler,  James  W.,  "Interdepartmental  Relations  in  the  Field  Service  of  the  Federal 
Government,"  op.  fit.  above  in  note  13,  pp.  52-55. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  287 

of  Agriculture,  and  the  war  agencies'  informal  gatherings  in  Boston  and 
other  cities.47  Field  training  programs,  wide  distribution  of  annual  reports 
of  all  agencies  and  the  United  States  Government  Manual,  and  possibly 
the  preparation  of  a  consolidated  federal  annual  report  for  each  region 
or  state,  are  additional  ways  of  spreading  awareness  of  other  agencies' 
activities.  The  element  of  physical  proximity  of  cooperating  officials  de- 
pends necessarily  upon  the  success  of  the  movement  for  greater  uniformity 
in  choice  of  field  offices,  and  upon  greater  emphasis  toward  getting  most 
federal  offices  in  the  same  city  into  a  single  building. 

A  specific  objective  and  a  limited  number  of  participants  are  essential 
to  effective  coordination.  "Coordination  in  general"  is  an  illusion.  The 
greatest  results  come  when  a  few  officials  having  vital  interest  in  some  par- 
ticular joint  problem  meet  for  the  purpose  of  finding  a  specific  answer  to 
it.48  Otherwise,  there  is  no  focal  point  for  discussion  and  no  interest 
capable  of  sustaining  the  coordinative  effort.  Approximately  equal  status 
of  the  participants  is  also  important,  for  two  reasons.  Each  cooperating 
official  should  be  able  to  speak  with  a  degree  of  authority  for  his  agency 
equivalent  to  that  of  the  representatives  of  the  other  agencies.  This  ability 
depends  on  the  extent  to  which  authority  within  each  agency  has  beer 
decentralized.  Each  participant  should  also  speak  with  reference  to  ap- 
proximately the  same  area  as  the  other  officials.  This  in  turn  depends 
on  the  degree  of  identity  of  regional  boundaries  marking  out  the  juris- 
dictions of  the  cooperating  officials. 

Regional  Coordtnafors.\^Aost  coordination  is  at  present  effected  througt 
direct  contact  between  field  officials  of  the  agencies  which  need  to  geai 
their  activities  together.  The  fact  that  this  method  appears  not  wholl) 
adequate  underlies  the  suggestions  which  constantly  recur  for  establish 
ment  of  some  sort  of  a  presidential  agent  in  each  region  to  coordinate  al 
federal  field  officials  in  that  a^eaT^The  area  coordinators  of  the  formei 
Federal  Coordinating  Service,  subsequently  the  state  directors  of  the  Na 
tional  Emergency  Council,  and  more  recently  the  field  office  heads  of  th< 
Bureau  of  the  Budget  have  been  the  principal  responses  to  this  need.  On< 
of  the  main  problems  is  to  isolate  the  functions  that  such  a  presidentia 
agent  should  perform,  assuming  that  he  cannot  match  the  French  prefec 
in  diversity  of  powers. 

Each  state  director  of  the  National  Emergency  Council  was  instructed 
"(a)  to  operate  a  bureau  of  information  concerning  the  federal  agencie! 
and  their  activities;  (b)  to  promote  cooperation  among  federal  agencies 
(c)  to  act  as  a  liaison  officer  between  the  federal  agencies  and  the  stat< 
administration;  and  (d)  to  report  biweekly  to  Washington  on  the  progres 

47  See  Dobbs,  John  M.,  "Interagency  Communication  at  the  Regional  Level ,"  Public  Ad 
ministration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  64-67. 

48  See  Gant,  George  F.,  "Bureaucracy  in  the  Field,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1943 
Vol.  3,  pp.  364-369,  esp.  p.  368. 


288  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

of  each  federal  agency  in  the  state,  critically  appraising  the  effectiveness 
of  its  work  and  analyzing  the  adequacy  of  the  federal  program  to  meet  the 
needs."49  His  jxjcin  gromqting  interagency  cooperation  anriripgrpH  very 
largely  a  Migg^Hnn^  far  "regggf]  ^gnygngfg."  Each  of  these 

would  convene  and  preside  at  meetings  of  representatives  of  various 
agencies;  use  his  persuasive  powers  to  stimulate  cooperation;  keep  himself 
informed  on  all  questions  of  common  concern;  and  report  to  some  central 
agency,  preferably  attached  to  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President,  "on 
the  region  as  a  whole,  unsolved  problems,  regional  cooperation  or  its  ab- 
sence, the  need  for  central  decision  with  respect  to  particular  controversies, 

and  the  like."     In  addition,  h£  might  h*"  "gfj  a?  g-rpyrinna^rKifrafnr  wk*»n 

the  conflicting  agencies  agreed  on  his  assuming  such  a  role.  He  might  also 
directly  supervise  all  central  institutional  services.50 

A  monograph  of  the  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Manage- 
ment proposed  regional  representatives  of  the  President  or  of  a  central 
staff  agency  who  would  act  in  three  capacities.  They  would  serve  as 
neutral  conciliators  of  interagency  conflicts  in  the  field  and  report  irrecon- 
cilable disputes  to  Washington,  where  a  solution  could  be  found  more 
effectively.  They  would  foster  mutual  acquaintance  and  familiarity  with 
all  agencies'  field  programs  among  field  officials,  through  sponsorship  of 
local  federal  business  associations  and  statewide  meetings  of  ranking  fed- 
eral officials  in  each  state.  And  they  would  make  special  administrative 
studies  constituting  audits  of  the  effectiveness  of  field  programs  of  particular 
agencies  and  of  the  total  pattern  of  federal  field  activities  in  a  given  area.51 

Special  Coordinative  Machinery.  All  of  these  experiments  and  proposals 
indicate  a  need  for  affirmative  steps  directed  toward  interagency  coordina- 
tion in  the  field.  Concern  with  this  need  is  a  responsibility  of  the  Bureau 
of  the  Budget.  In  1943  it  described  the  functions  of  its  field  offices  as  fol- 
lows: "to  counsel  and  advise  with  federal  officials  in  the  field  for  the  pur- 
pose of  getting  better  coordination  of  federal  programs  and  better  rela- 
tions among  the  federal  agencies  in  the  field;  to  consult  with  officials  of 
state  and  local  government  on  the  operation  of  federal  programs  of  con- 
cern to  them  and  to  report  to  bureau  headquarters  problems  arising  in  these 
relationships,  with  recommendations  for  their  solution;  to  examine  and 
recommend  improvements  in  the  utilization  of  supplies  and  equipment  in 
the  field;  and  to  make  administrative  studies  on  the  initiative  of  the  field 
offices  or  at  the  request  of  other  bureau  staffs,  to  make  recommendations 
for  more  efficient  operations  and  to  report  to  bureau  headquarters  those 

49  Cf.  Feslcr,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  45,  p.  282;  sec  also  pp.  283-287  for  a  critical  ap- 
praisal of  the  National  Emergency  Council's  field  service.  For  a  concurring  view,  see  Mac- 
mahon,  Millett  and  Ogden,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  12,  p.  241  ff. 

00  Special  Copimittee  on  Comparative  Administration,  Committee  on  Public  Adminis- 
tration, Social  Science  Research  Council,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  3,  pp.  12,  21-23. 

51  Fcslcr,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  45,  p.  292  ff. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  289 

problems  requiring  special  study  or  action  or  a  policy  statement  or  guide 
from  headquarters."82 

In  addition,  passing  note  should  be  taken  of  regional  committees  and 
boards,  especially  during  World  War  II,  organized  by  functional  agencies 
having  coordinative  responsibilities  affecting  a  number  of  agencies.  Ex- 
amples are  the  regional  advisory  councils  of  the  Office  of  Defense  Health 
and  Welfare  Services;53  the  local  work  of  the  Committee  for  Congested 
Areas;54  the  manpower  priorities  committees  of  the  War  Manpower  Com- 
mission; and  the  area  production  urgency  committees  of  the  War  Pro- 
duction Board.  One  of  the  fundamental  advantages  of  such  committees  is 
that  each  has  a  specific  objective,  in  contrast  to  regional  coordinators,  whose 
very  universality  of  interest  may  dull  their  effectiveness. 

5.  THE  PROSPECTS  OF  JOINT  FIELD  PLANNING 

Much  of  the  interagency  coordination  discussed  above  assumes  tha 
policy  is  formulated  at  headquarters  and  that  the  function  of  field  official; 
is  primarily  to  carry  central  programs  into  execution.  A  radical  departure 
from  such  a  premise  is  the  view  that  policy  itself  should  be  formulated  a 
the  regional  level.  Two  principal  instruments  have  been  evolved  for  thi 
purpose:  the  regional  planning  commission;  and  the  regional  developmen 
authority. 

Regional  Planning  Commissions.  J&egional  planning— commissions,  as 
they  have  evolved  in  the  United  States,  haye_  been^  primarily  de$ignedLto 
qomplcmgnt  the  work  of  state  planning  boards.  Their  membership  has 
generally  stemmecTTiroirr  these  statef  boards."  Still,  field  representatives  of 
federal  agencies  have  actively  collaborated  in  important  staff  studies  that 
have  strongly  influenced  the  work  of  the  commissions.  The  noteworthy 
1942  report  of  the  Southeastern  Regional  Planning  Commission,  for  example, 
was  prepared  with  the  aid  of  the  National  Resources  Planning  Board,  Tenn- 
essee Valley  Authority,  Forest  Service,  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics, 
National  Park  Service,  Army  Corps  of  Engineers,  Federal  Power  Com- 
mission, United  States  Housing  Authority,  and  Work  Projects  Adminis- 
tration.55 The  National  Resources  Planning  Board,  which  provided  vigor- 
ous federal  sponsorship  of  both  regional  planning  commissions  and  state 
planning  boards,  has  been  abolished.  However,  continuance  of  planning 
activities  at  regional  and  state  levels  is  to  be  expected.56 

52  Latham,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  41,  p.  19. 

M  A  penetrating  analysis  of  this  experience,  which  has  general  as  well  as  specific  value, 
is  provided  by  Roseman,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  21. 

64  See  Gill,  Corrington,  "Federal-State-City  Cooperation  in  Congested  Production  Areas," 
Public  Administration  Review.  1945,  Vol.  5,  pp.  28-33. 

55  National  Resources  Planning  Board,  Regional  Planning:  Part  XI — The  Southeast,  Wash- 
ington: Government  Printing  Office,  1942. 

56  See  Mcrriam,  Charles  £.,  "The  National  Resources  Planning  Board:    A  Chapter  in 
American  Planning  Experience,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  pp.  1075- 
1088. 


290  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

Regional  planning  commissions  prepare  very  valuable  reports  that  serve 
to  crystallize  desiraBle^policics  for  long-rang£jTgional  development.  But 
"sHcIT  reports  lack  any  reliable  implementing  mechanism.  Planning  and 
execution  are  treated  as  two  distinct  fields,  and  the  integration  of  planning 
through  regional  commissions  is  not  matched  by  a  similar  integration  of 
execution.  Instead,  dozens  of  federal,  state,  and  local  agencies  are  free 
to  accept  or  reject  the  proposals  of  the  planners'  reports.  The  reports, 
therefore,  are  primarily  educational  in  purpose.  They  fall  short  of  the 
conception  in  many  minds  of  the  need  for  capitalizing  on  the  vitality 
of  regional  consciousness  and  for  translating  regional  planning  into  con- 
crete results. 

Regional  Development  Authorities.  These  reactions  to  the  approach  of 
regional  planning  commissions  result  in  a  hospitable  reception  for  the 
idea  of  regional  development  authorities  modeled  on  the  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority.  Such  authorities  provide  a  focus  both  for_planning  and  for 
action.  They  themselves  possess  corriprehefldve  authority,  granted  by~Con- 
gress,  to  perform  any  functions  necessary  to  the  development  of  the  re- 
sources of  the  region.  Yet,  if  animated  by  the  spirit  of  TV  A,  authorities 
of  this  kind  may  also  endeavor  to  bring  other  federal  agencies,  as  well 
as  state  and  local  agencies,  into  cooperative  planning  and  administration. 
Such  efforts  are  facilitated  by  the  financial  aid  the  regional  authority  can 
offer  the  functional  agencies,  and  by  the  reluctance  of  functional  agencies 
to  be  "frozen  out"  of  any  region  by  the  former.57 

The  case  for  integrated  resources  development  on  a  regional  basis  has 
been  stated  enthusiastically  and  persuasively  in  recent  years.58  The  success 
of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  has  provided  seemingly  incontrovertible 
proof  of  the  wisdom  of  this  approach.  The  President  and  many  members 
of  Congress  have  reacted  favorably  to  the  numerous  bills  for  a  Missouri 
Valley  Authority,  a  Columbia  Valley  Authority,  and  similar  new  agencies 
focusing  on  water  and  related  resources.  The  difficulty  of  a  region's  water- 
resource  development  has  always  lain  in  the  fact  that  such  development  is 
subject  to  the  mercies  of  the  Army  Corps  of  Engineers,  Bureau  of  Reclama- 
tion, Federal  Power  Commission,  Department  of  Agriculture,  Public  Health 
Service,  Fish  and  Wildlife  Service,  National  Park  Service,  and  other  func- 
tional agencies.  This  difficulty  could  presumably  be  met  by  giving  each 
region  of  the  country  a  single  development  authority.  Decisions  for  the 
region  would  be  made  in  the  region,  close  to  the  people.  They  would  fit 
together  into  a  consistent  pattern  for  the  region,  and  not  clash  as  is  the 
case  when  each  of  a  dozen  federal  agencies  pursues  its  own  independent 
path.  Planning  and  execution  would  be  tied  together  and  not  be  isolated 

^  See  Pritchett,  C.  Herman,  The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  pp.  116-140,  Chapel  Hill: 
University  of  North  Carolina  Press,  1943;  Fesler,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  45,  pp.  288-290. 
**  Notably  by  Lilienthal,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  8. 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  291 

from  each  other,  as  occurs  under  the  approach  of  the  regional  planning  com- 
missions. 

Function  Versus  Area.  The  issue  is  not  new.  It  is  the  ancient  conflict 
between  function  and  area.  Both  are  necessary,  yet  one  must  have  primacy 
The  issue  is  also  a  reflection  in  the  field  of  a  problem  of  the  center:  Ho\v 
to  group  functions  and  bureaus  into  a  logical  departmental  structure  at 
headquarters;  how  to  strengthen  the  department  head's  authority  to  inte- 
grate the  work  of  bureaus  that  have  established  a  tradition  of  autonomy; 
and  how  to  provide  effective  interdepartmental  collaboration  in  planning 
and  execution  of  programs  involving  the  interests  of  more  than  one  agency. 
In  other  words,  the  question  of  regional  development  authorities  arises  in 
part  because  at  headquarters  there  has  been  no  effective  coordination  of 
agencies  dealing  with  water  and  other  natural  resources. 

The  most  notable  lack  of  coordination  is  the  long-standing  rivalry  be- 
tween the  Army  Corps  of  Engineers,  with  its  primary  interest  in  naviga- 
tion and  flood  control,  and  the  Bureau  of  Reclamation  of  the  Interior 
Department,  with  its  emphasis  on  irrigation  and  reclamation.  These  two 
agencies  are  the  principal  dam  builders  of  the  federal  government.  Neither 
has  heretofore  had  a  fundamental  interest  in  the  generation  of  electric 
power.  In  the  Pacific  Northwest,  the  Bonneville  project  was  built  by  the 
Engineers,  Grand  Coulee  by  the  Bureau  of  Reclamation,  while  distribution 
of  the  power  was  made  a  responsibility  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Interior. 

Remaining  Issues.  If  the  shortcut  solution  of  such  problems  is  the 
establishment  of  regional  development  authorities,  certain  remaining  issues 
need  clarification.  First,  the  key  problems  of  the  Tennessee  valley  are  not 
identical  with  the  key  problems  of  other  regions.  As  between  the  Tennessee 
valley  and  the  Columbia  valley,  for  instance,  entirely  different  emphases 
must  be  placed  on  soil  erosion,  flood  control,  irrigation,  domestic  water 
supplies,  fishing,  lumbering,  and  land  ownership.59 

Second,  j:he  functional  jurisdictions  of_rcgigjialNdcvclopmcnt  authorities 
will  have  to  bp  precisely  defined.  The  warmest  advocates  ot  development 
autKorities  make  no  pretense  that  their  technique  is  applicable  to  any  gov- 
ernmental problems  other  than  unified  development  of  natural  resources- 
water,  land,  minerals,  forests.60  The  regional  authorities,  therefore,  are  not 
a  transplantation  from  abroad  of  the  prefectural  system.  Many  regula- 
tory and  service  functions  must  continue  to  be  performed  by  field  agents 
of  central  agencies. 

iThird,  the  fate  of  Washington  bureaus  concerned  with  resources  must 
be  'determined.  If  ten  or  twelve  development  authorities  blanket  the  coun- 
try, will  there  be  any  need  for  well-staffed  central  agencies  such  as  the 
Forest  Service,  National  Park  Service,  Federal  Power  Commission,  Depart- 


59  See  McWilliams,  Carey,  "Columbia  River  Bureaucrats,"  Nation,  June  23,  1945,  Vol.  160, 
p.  694. 

®°  Cf.  Lilienthal,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  8,  p.  168. 


292  FIELD  ORGANIZATION 

ment  of  Agriculture,  and  Bureau  of  Reclamation?  If  not,  will  the  public 
lose  some  governmental  efficiency  through  the  breaking  up  of  these  special- 
ized staffs?  And  will  the  public  suffer  increased  taxes  to  support  ten  or 
twelve  specialized  staffs  for  each  resources  function? 

Fourth,  the  areas  of  regional  development  authorities  must  be  care- 
fully defined  if  they  are  not  to  overlap  and  so  lead  to  confused  responsibility 
qnd  "border  fighting."  Contrary  to  general  impressions,  the  Tennessee 
Valley  Authority  has  no  precise  boundaries  for  its  marketing  of  electric 
power.  It  markets  its  power  well  beyond  the  valley  where  the  power  is 
generated. 

Finally,  there  has  to  be  some  machinery  for  general  supervision  of  the 
authorities  by  the  federal  government.  The  concept  of  autonomous  au- 
thorities clearly  responsible  neither  to  the  people's  representatives  at  Wash- 
ington nor  directly  to  regional  constituencies  is  opposed  to  the  democratic 
tradition.  There  are  three  possible  answers:  to  make  the  authorities  re- 
sponsible directly  to  the  President;  to  make  them  responsible  to  some 
supervisory  unit  located  in  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President;  or  to  make 
them  responsible  to  the  Secretary  of  the  Interior.61 

Community-Level  Analysis.  We  have  noticed  that  the  regional  plan- 
ning commissions  take  a  very  broad  viewpoint  and  provide  no  effective 
link  between  planning  and  execution.  The  regional  development  authori- 
ties in  their  more  ambitious  form  are  a  revolutionary  abandonment  of 
functional  administration  of  resources  by  the  federal  government.  In  addi- 
tion, they  leave  unanswered  the  question  of  joint  field  planning  of  non- 
resource  activities.  More  modest  and  more  short-range  in  objective  than 
either  of  these  proposals  is  a  third  approach  to  program  planning:  com- 
munity-level analysis  of  the  impact  of  federal  programs. 

This  approach  emphasizes  that  federal  administration,  however  greatly 
it  be  functionally  segmented,  must  make  sense  at  the  level  where  its  mul- 
tiple activities  come  in  direct  contact  with  citizens  and  the  communities  in 
which  they  live.  It  is  at  this  administrative  "firing  line,"  therefore,  that  the 
actual  interaction  of  federal  operations  can  best  be  observed.  The  symptoms 
of  confusion,  overlapping  of  authority,  or  neglect  of  citizens'  needs  can  be 
isolated  and  reported  to  headquarters  and  to  that  regional  agent  of  the 
chief  executive  who  may  have  the  task  of  interagency  coordination.  It 
should  not  be  forgotten  that  a  majority  of  interagency  difficulties  in  the 
field  are  caused — and  can  only  be  remedied — by  action  at  the  central  level.62 

The  best  solution  would  seem  to  be  for  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget's  field 

01  See  Hansen,  Alvin  H.  and  PcrlofT,  Harvey  S.,  Regional  Resource  Development,  p.  30 
ff.,  National  Planning  Association  Planning  Pamphlet  No.  16,  Washington,  1942;  Cooke, 
Morris  L.,  "Who  Shall  Boss  the  MVA?"  New  Republic,  April  16,  1945,  Vol.  112,  p.  499; 
Pincus,  William,  "Shall  We  Have  More  TVA's?"  Public  Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5, 
pp.  148-152. 

42  See  Feslcr,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  45,  p.  292.  See  also  White,  Leonard  D.,  "Field 
Coordination  in  Liberated  Areas/'  Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  p.  189  £ 


FIELD  ORGANIZATION  293 

offices  to  make  studies  in  sample  communities  or  counties  covering  the  total 
impact  of  Federal  programs,63  report  the  results  to  Budget  Bureau  head- 
quarters, and  thereby  stimulate  remedial  action  at  the  center  and  in  the 
field.  Corrective  action  could  be  backed  by  the  authority  of  the  Executive 
Office  of  the  President  and  the  controls  available  through  budgetary  review 
and  quarterly  apportionment  of  appropriated  funds.  Such  a  method  of 
assuring  that  federal  programs  fit  together  is  no  substitute,  of  course,  for  the 
broad-gauged  work  of  regional  planning  commissions  and  regional  develop- 
ment authorities.  However,  it  does  afford  a  constant  test  of  the  short-range 
effectiveness  of  federal  programs  and  provides  machinery  for  correcting 
such  defects  as  are  discovered. 


63  Even  more  useful  would  be  sample  area  surveys  of  the  impact  of  federal,  state,  and 
local  programs,  the  reports  to  be  a  basis  for  action  by  all  three  governmental  levels.  Some 
experimental  studies  of  this  character  have  already  been  undertaken;  to  some  extent  the 
reports  of  regional  planning  commissions  are  examples  of  this  approach.  Mention  may  also  be 
made  of  the  sample  studies  carried  on  under  auspices  of  the  Council  on  Intergovernmental 
Relations. 


CHAPTER 


Informal  Organization 

1.  FORMAL  AND  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

Organic  Growth  of  Informal  Organization.  This  chapter  is  to  deal 
with  some  of  the  organizational  and  operational  implications  of  the  difference 
between  authority  and  influence,  between  the  legal  power  of  command 
to  direct  the  behavior  of  others  and  the  human  capacity  for  getting  others 
to  see  things  your  way  so  that  they  will  act  and  even  want  to  act  accord- 
ingly. How  this  difference  affects  the  role  of  the  chief  executive  we  have 
noticed  earlier,1  but  the  matter  has  wider  significance.  It  can  hardly 
escape  the  sharp-eyefl  /observer  that  administrative  bodies — and  indeed  all 
organizations,  whether  legislatures,  political  parties,  labor  unions,  business 
enterprises,  universities,  churches,  armies,  or  professional  associations — 
respond  in  fact  to  a  variety  of  informal  patterns  of  influence  among  their 
membership.2  These  are  more  or  less  at  variance  with  the  acknowledged 
structure  of  formal  authority  on  which  the  organization  rests. 

It  is  therefore  easy  to  understand  that  an  essential  object  of  successful 
administrative  leadership  must  be  to  provide  the  integrating  forces  that 
will  draw  all  eyes  toward  common  goals.  In  small  groups  where  authority 
is  mainly  the  product  of  conceded  superiority  rather  than  of  legal  designa- 
tion, the  distinctive  effect  of  influence  may  blend  completely  with  this  kind 
of  nonlegal  authority.  As  soon  as  the  group  grows  larger,  however,  formal 
authority  may  set  itself  apart  from  leadership.  While  the  boss  naturally 
will  want  to  run  the  show,  every  one  else  in  the  group,  no  less  naturally, 
will  want  to  be  as  independent  as  possible,  and  will  have  his  own  notions 
of  how  the  show  ought  to  be  run.  Such  individualistic  impulses  never  fully 
subside  in  any  organization.  They  give  rise  to  the  cell  formation  typical  of 
informal  organization. 

Charts  and  Realities.  The  organization  chart — which  most  modern  organ- 


1  See  above  Ch.  8,  "The  Chief  Executive,"  sec.  2,  "Leadership  and  Authority." 

2  For  the  increasing  interest  of  students  of  management  in  this  area  of  behavior,  see  above 
Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  4,  "The  Frontiers  of  Research," 

294 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  295 

izations  require  as  a  source  of  self-respect—shows  the  formal  structure,  labels 
the  jurisdiction  assigned  to  each  component  unit,  and  indicates  the  lines 
of  hierarchical  authority  established  to  regulate  the  conduct  of  business. 
If  the  chart  is  carefully  and  candidly  drawn,  the  very  act  of  preparing  it  is 
almost  sure  to  disclose  internal  ambiguities  calling  for  resolution.  If  a  clari- 
fication of  these  is  a  by-product  of  completing  the  chart,  the  labor  of  the 
chartmaker  is  already  repaid  in  the  smoother  operations  that  can  be  ex- 
pected to  result  from  a  better  understanding  of  working  relationships  among 
the  various  groups  of  employees.  At  best,  however,  the  organization  chart 
is  ordinarily  and  necessarily  an  idealized  picture  of  the  intents  of  top  man- 
agement, a  reflection  of  hopes  and  aims  rather  than  a  photograph  of  the 
operating  facts  within  the  organization.  To  the  sophisticated  reader,  the 
chart  is  a  useful  guide  to  further  questions. 

To  begin  with,  the  chart,  while  locating  present  personnel,  speaks  rather 
in  terms  of  positions  than  of  live  employees.  In  such  an  inevitably  com- 
posite abstraction  of,  say,  all  possible  P-5  economists,  we  have  no  clue  about 
the  kind  of  man  who  might  be  heading  the  Analysis  Section  in  the  Import 
Division,  about  the  standing  he  has  in  his  section  or  in  the  division,  or 
about  the  load  of  work  he  carries  or  has  failed  to  carry.  Is  he  the  faithful 
technician  who  as  a  lowly  and  anenymous  assistant  to  the  previous  section 
head  used  to  get  up  the  figures  to  support  the  division's  policy  and  who  as 
the  "logical"  successor  now  fondles  the  same  series  of  figures  even  though 
changing  conditions  call  for  an  imaginative  and  fresh  analysis  of  foreign 
trade?  Or  is  he  the  man  who  was  borrowed  from  the  Research  Division  on 
a  temporary  detail  to  work  out  a  particular  problem  before  the  Import 
Division  had  an  Analysis  Section  of  its  own,  and  who  impressed  the  division 
chief  so  much  that  the  section  was  created  to  keep  him  around? 

Again,  was  he  perhaps  the  only  promising  reinforcement  the  division  chief 
could  think  of  in  order  to  bolster  an  ailing  operation,  with  the  position 
of  section  head  happening  to  be  the  handiest  vacancy  to  bring  him  into  the 
picture?  Or,  to  suggest  only  one  more  line  of  possibilities,  is  the  position 
again  vacant  today  as  we  look  at  the  organization  chart?  If  so,  is  a  replace- 
ment in  sight  and  the  section's  work  still  definitely  part  of  the  whole  pro- 
gram? Or  is  the  place  not  to  be  filled  and  the  section  to  be  disbanded,  so 
that  its  box  in  the  chart  has  already  turned  into  an  anachronism?  Plainly, 
we  would  need  answers  not  only  to  these  and  many  more  questions  about 
our  P-5  economist,  but  also  to  similar  questions  about  the  division  chief 
one  step  above  and  others  in  adjoining  positions,  before  attempting  to  draw 
from  the  chart  an  appraisal  of  his  role  as  the  head  of  the  Analysis  Section. 

Attitudes  and  Motivations.  However  he  appears  on  the  chart,  this  P-5 
stands  in  a  different  light  to  his  own  subordinates  in  the  section.  Here  he  is 
the  boss,  clothed  with  authority  to  summon  and  direct,  and  all  his  qualities 
of  leadership  are  at  stake  in  the  assessment  of  what  that  authority  is  worth. 
To  the  oldtimer  in  the  section— say,  with  a  standing  assignment  to  tabulate 


296  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

the  weekly  figures  of  customs  receipts — he  may  be  only  another  boss,  more 
or  less  like  those  that  have  come  and  gone,  to  be  viewed  with  indifference 
unless  it  should  occur  to  the  section  head  that  the  customs  figures  ought 
to  be  compiled  differently,  or  possibly  are  no  longer  needed  at  all.  If  he 
lets  people  alone  who  know  their  tasks  and  do  them  without  prodding,  he 
is  a  safe  boss;  and  a  safe  boss  is  a  good  boss  in  the  oldtimer's  way  of 
thinking. 

To  one  of  the  junior  economists,  however,  the  boss  may  be  the  author 
of  that  series  of  articles  which  broke  new  ground  in  the  analysis  of  the 
balance  of  international  payments.  This  junior  may  have  studied  the  same 
field,  and  is  cherishing  a  hope  that  the  boss  will  develop  it  within  the 
section — a  prospect  rich  in  possibilities  of  new  assignments  and  recogni- 
tion for  the  alert  youngster.  Another  junior  of  the  same  rank,  though,  who 
because  of  his  addiction  to  doctrinal  heresies  was  passed  over  whenever 
the  previous  section  head  had  an  especially  interesting  project  to  assign,  is 
thoroughly  alarmed  to  find  that  the  new  head  also  has  a  blind  spot  regarding 
these  doctrines.  Convinced  that  he  is  facing  a  hopeless  situation,  he  has 
already  begun  to  make  discreet  inquiries  about  possible  openings  in  other 
parts  of  the  agency.  In  a  sense,  his  mind  is  no  longer  on  the  job. 

All  of  these  variables  must  be  accounted  for  in  the  staff  pattern  before 
we  can  have  much  of  an  idea  of  the  concrete  work  situation.  And  so  with 
the  girls  in  the  section.  One  or  two  of  them  can  be  counted  on  to  stay 
overtime  if  needed,  to  get  out  the  materials  the  boss  has  to  have  for  his 
conference  the  first  thing  in  the  morning.  The  others  feel  that  if  he  cannot 
arrange  to  get  his  work  done  during  office  hours,  they  are  under  no  duty  to 
bail  him  out. 

Basis  of  Personal  Organization.  Given  the  crew  our  section  head  has 
to  work  with — and  allowing  for  such  additions  and  eliminations  as  he  can 
manage  from  time  to  time — he  develops  a  team  for  his  purposes.  He  leans 
on  the  strengths  he  finds,  and  by-passes  the  weaknesses.  He  looks  to  a 
smaller  nucleus  of  people  for  the  crucial  work,  and  he  meets  with  them 
more  often.  Together  they  look  ahead  and  lay  plans,  assemble  the  strategic 
information  and  put  it  into  persuasive  form,  carry  the  argument  when  the 
occasion  for  it  arises,  and  consolidate  the  advance  when  their  program  has 
won  endorsement.  This  is  the  section  head's  personal  organization — perhaps 
no  more  than  a  thought-man,  an  action-man,  and  a  personal  secretary. 
Organization  charts  are  silent  on  the  relationships  that  constitute  such 
personal  organizations. 

The  factors  here  considered  center  around  the  measure  of  influence  that 
our  hypothetical  subordinate— the  section  head— may  exert  on  his  imme- 
diate superior  and  on  his  own  section.  The  example  is  taken  from  the 
middle  ranks  in  the  scale  of  positions,  and  from  a  staff  or  auxiliary  function 
in  the  organization's  work— for  the  Analysis  Section  presumably  does  not 
actually  issue  the  licenses  that  are,  let  us  say,  the  end  product  of  the  divi- 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  297 

sion's  operation.  If  we  shift  our  example  upward  or  downward  in  the 
hierarchy,  or  from  a  staff  or  auxiliary  section  to  an  operating  section,  some 
of  the  situations  indicated  are  no  longer  so  plausible,  while  other  new  possi- 
bilities open  up.  In  particular,  the  higher  we  go  up  the  line,  the  more 
complex  the  relationships  become. 

Growing  and  Shrinking  Organizations.  Again,  we  have  assumed  an 
example  from  a  stable  organization.  But  organization  charts  are  drawn 
also  for  rapidy  expanding  agencies.  In  1942,  for  instance,  the  war  agencies 
were  recruiting  personnel  at  an  almost  overwhelming  rate  as  they  struggled 
to  cope  with  the  new  tasks  that  had  brought  them  into  being.  As  their 
functions  grew,  their  internal  structure  and  external  relationships  altered. 
Successive  newcomers  in  these  agencies  caught  hold  and  came  to  exert 
decisive  influence,  or  failed  to  catch  hold  and  dropped  out  of  sight.  From 
month  to  month,  under  the  impact  of  these  changes,  organization  charts 
.became  obsolete  more  rapidly  than  maps  of  Europe.**  In  the  same  way, 
during  the  months  that  followed  the  close  of  hostilities  in  1945,  contraction 
or  liquidation  and  atrophy  of  functions  were  the  order  of  the  day  for  most 
of  these  agencies.  Once  more,  the  patterns  of  influence  within  the  organi- 
zation in  many  cases  changed  abruptly. 

In  short,  the  chart  portrays  the  norms  of  anatomy.  We  must  look  to 
the  informal  organization  to  understand  the  physiology — perhaps  the  path- 
ology—of the  organism,  and  the  dynamics  of  its  behavior. 

2.  ELEMENTS  OF  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

Characteristic  Factors.  The  network  of  influence  does  not  extend  from 
any  single  center — even,  it  may  be  suspected,  under  such  a  well-consoli- 
dated regime  as  the  prewar  Soviet  system,  which  did  not  mind  the  burden 
on  military  discipline  arising  from  the  institution  of  political  commissars 
in  the  Red  Army.  Certainly  in  the  more  familiar  field  of  our  own  federal 
administration,  relationships  based  on  influence  result  rather  from  the  inter- 
play of  a  combination  of  factors.  Some  are  unique  to  the  particular  scene. 
Others  are  recurringly  characteristic  of  many  agencies  and  situations. 

Among  the  latter  we  may  discern:  (1)  the  relation  of  the  actual  leader- 
ship sensed  within  the  organization  to  the  formal  location  of  authority; 
(2)  the  personal  organizations  installed  or  recognized  by  the  leaders  within 
the  framework  of  the  formal  structure,  to  transmit  direction  and  keep  the 
leaders  posted  on  internal  conditions;  and  (3)  the  ties  of  allegiances,  external 
and  internal,  that  cut  across  hierarchical  levels  and  bind  together  groups  of 
officials  and  employees  on  some  other  basis  than  that  of  loyalty  to  their 
formal  superiors.  It  is  useful  also  to  distinguish  the  role  of  these  informal 
groupings  as  supplementary  channels  of  communication  and  intelligence 
from  their  potentialities  for  furthering  or  hindering  the  acknowledged  aims 
of  the  organization.  These  points  call  for  some  elaboration. 

Self-Expression  of  Influence.  The  magnetism  of  personal  leadership  is 


298  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

an  irrepressible  and  often  an  unpredictable  force.  Responsibility  will  fre- 
quently evoke  it  unexpectedly  in  the  head  of  an  organization  that  is  sud- 
denly subjected  to  new  conditions  and  pressing  problems.  However,  leader- 
ship may  fail  to  appear  at  the  point  where  there  was  every  reason  to  count 
on  it,  and  instead  turn  up  elsewhere  in  the  organization.  It  may  indeed  be 
ordinarily  denied  to  the  titular  head  of  the  organization  by  the  very  process 
of  his  selection. 

Nomination  for  the  presidency,  to  take  a  conspicuous  case,  usually  does 
not  go  to  a  man  showing  exceptional  personal  qualities  of  independent 
leadership  if  the  party  chieftains  who  control  the  convention  can  feel  confi- 
dent of  winning  with  a  more  manageable  Jand  dependable  candidate.  The 
chairmanship  of  a  congressional  committee,  where  seniority  commonly  gov- 
erns, will  only  by  accident  fall  to  the  dominant  personality  of  the  commit- 
tee. Cabinet  officers  must  often  be  chosen  in  recognition  of  claims  other 
than  the  leadership  they  can  promise  in  running  their  departments.  And 
so  with  administrative  appointments.  The  conditions  of  selection  too  seldom 
permit  native  qualities  of  personal  leadership  to  be  the  decisive  criterion. 
Except  for  a  new  agency  with  an  active  head  who  is  also  its  actual  leader, 
or  for  a  crisis  in  the  life  of  an  older  agency  that  gives  a  new  head  an  un- 
usually free  hand  for  reorganization,  the  typical  situation  therefore  shows  a 
distribution  of  leadership  through  the  organization  that  does  not  coincide 
with  formal  authority.  All  such  leadership  begets  loyalty,  and  loyalty 
commands  influence. 

Obviously,  nominal  authority  does  not  work  in  a  vacuum;  the  leadership 
is  somewhere.  A  capable  department  head  may  be  given  jurisdiction  over 
an  unrelated  operation,  because  the  operators  must  report  to  some  one,  and 
no  better  place  for  allocation  of  the  function  has  appeared.  If  the  jurisdic- 
tion is  already  in  satisfactory  hands,  it  may  be  left  alone.  Authority  to  this 
extent  tends  to  follow  the  pull  of  leadership.  Much  the  same  is  true  within 
the  departmental  organization  itself  and  within  each  of  its  component 
parts. 

Because  one  of  the  chief  staff  officers  serving  as  immediate  advisers  to 
the  department  head  may  have  demonstrated  special  capacity  for  achieving 
internal  agreements  or  for  sound  political  judgment  or  simply  for  getting 
work  done  more  promptly  than  others,  he  is  used  more  and  more  as  a 
privileged  source  of  counsel  and  assistance.  Difficult  problems — including 
those  outside  his  formal  jurisdiction — drift  to  him  automatically  from  the 
desk  of  the  top  executive.  Other  staff  officers,  and  line  officials  as  well,  dis- 
cover that  it  is  wise  for  them  to  check  with  this  colleague  in  advance  on  all 
problematical  matters  handed  up  to  the  department  head.  In  the  end,  the 
staff  officer  may  be  doing  the  job  of  a  permanent  undersecretary,  while  the 
nominal  undersecretary  shifts  his  attention  to  matters  of  special  interest  to 
him.  Or,  in  a  given  bureau,  division,  or  section,  the  employee  who  estab- 
lishes himself  as  a  key  man  will  grow  in  stature  as  his  responsibilities 
expand  de  facto  by  spontaneous  accrual 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  299 

No  doubt,  such  developments  introduce  into  the  hierarchical  structure 
much-needed  flexibility.  They  allow  an  organization  to  make  the  most  of  its 
strength  wherever  such  strength  resides.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  also 
evident  that  as  a  consequence  the  organization  may  develop  all  kinds  of 
unorthodox  bulges.  From  time  to  time  these  bulges  will  be  legalized,  so  to 
speak,  as  factual  influence  is  given  formal  status  through  the  redefinition 
of  authority  and  through  adjustments  in  the  channels  of  command.  How- 
ever, such  formalization  may  merely  aggravate  defects  in  internal  balance, 
structural  deformities,  and  lopsided  arrangements.  With  all  that,  the  sur- 
veyor of  organizational  structure  should  always  bear  in  mind  the  need  for 
reserving  judgment  until  all  compensating  advantages  of  a  seemingly  bizarre 
pattern  have  been  ascertained. '  A  department  is  not  likely  to  be  impressed 
with  the  criticism  that  its  organization  chart  looks  screwy  when  the  existing 
working  mechanisms  accord  with  the  operating  preferences  of  its  strongest 
personalities  and  are  adequately  understood  by  its  personnel. 

Variables  Affecting  Authority.  A  complicating  factor  arises  from  the 
dynamics  of  leadership.  Authority  as  expressed  in  legal  terms  is  essentially 
static.  Influence  is  susceptible  of  continuous  change.  Leadership  may  wane 
as  an  official  commanding  deference  shows  himself  unable  to  stand  the 
tough  grind  of  responsibility,  or  as  his  health  and  his  nerves  begin  to  falter, 
or  as  he  fails  to  withstand  the  jolts  and  shocks  of  temporary  defeats.  In- 
fluence is  competitive.  When  leaders  stumble  and  fall  by  the  wayside, 
rivals  will  meet  their  opportunity.  As  these  individuals  begin  to  inject  their 
personalities  into  the  stream  of  operations,  new  bulges  may  evolve  while 
earlier  ones  wither  away. 

The  actual  substance  of  authority  is  therefore  affected  by  a  wide  range 
of  factors.  To  support  itself,  authority  cannot  merely  point  to  its  insignia. 
It  must  seek  to  effect  constancy  of  deference.  -Thus  it  requires  a  basis  in 
persuasion.  It  must  nurture  itself  in  consent.  It  must  bargain  for  endorse- 
ment and  negotiate  workable  covenants  with  internal  forces  of  opposition. 
Administrative  orders,  while  traveling  downward  from  level  of  authority 
to  level  of  authority,  may  completely  change  their  meaning  when  they 
encounter  passive  resistance  or  open  antagonism.8  Authority  cannot  assert 
itself  when  its  claims  fail  to  rest  on  plausible  reason  or  commonly  shared 
attitudes.  To  a  large  extent,  therefore,  authority  must  be  buttressed  by 
rational  considerations  and  appeals.  That  is  why  some  students  regard  the 
top  executive  primarily  as  a  ratifying  agent-^one  who  sanctions  the  common 
thinking  of  his  organization.4  In  aiming  at  such  sanction,  he  must  prepare 
the  ground  by  shaping  common  thought. 

8  For  a  report  on  general  limitations  of  institutional  knowledge  about  policies  and  in- 
structions, see  Corson,  John  J.,  "Weak  Links  in  the  Chain  of  Command,"  Public  Opinion 
Quarterly,  1945,  Vol.  9,  p.  346  ff. 

4  See,  for  instance,  Coutrot,  Jean,  "Note  sur  la  Technique  du  Travail  en  Commission,' 
Administrative  Papers,  p.  46  ff.,  and  Morstem  Marx,  Fritz,  discussion  remarks,  Proceedings,  pp 
99-100,  Seventh  International  Management  Congress,  Washington,  1938.  The  same  basic  pom: 
is  implicit  in  McCormick,  Charles  P.,  Multiple  Management.  New  York,  Harper,  1938. 


300  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

Moreover,  the  exercise  of  authority  is  affected  by  the  nature  of  its  man- 
date, which  in  a  real  sense  is  always  in  flux.  The  statutory  formulation 
of  the  mission  of  an  administrative  organization  may  remain  the  same,  and 
yet  the  scope  of  actual  authority  reposing  in  the  top  executive  is  bound  to 
change  with  changing  circumstances.  Most  of  these  circumstances  are  be- 
yond his  own  control.  We  may  think  of  shifting  legislative  alignments, 
the  rise  and  fall  of  popular  causes,  reorientations  in  general  policy,  and 
even  deteriorating  public  relations  that  arrest  the  individual  agency  in  many 
ways.  These  variables  account  for  the  fact  that  there  are  always  matters 
of  great  administrative  significance  within  the  reach  of  the  legislative  man- 
date of  an  agency  which  its  top  executive  would  never  dare  to  touch  at 
certain  times.  Particular  issues  grow  too  hot  to  handle  while  others  cool 
off  in  the  battles  of  public  opinion  and  the  contests  of  political  forces.  The 
time-bound  cycles  of  popular  elections  also  play  their  role  in  determining 
the  actual  scope  of  legal  authority. 

Even  in  the  most  limited  sense — solely  in  reference  to  the  specific  incum- 
bent— the  place  of  formal  authority  is  one  of  relative  importance  only.  The 
official  vested  with  authority  may  be  personally  weak  or  strong,  timid  or 
aggressive,  unimaginative  or  intellectually  alert,  phlegmatic  or  choleric. 
The  same  span  of  legal  authority  will  furnish  different  individualities  with 
different  opportunities  for  initiative  and  leadership.  Even  in  reasonably 
stable  organizations,  changes  in  personnel  at  the  points  of  control  are  fre- 
quent enough  to  cause  conspicuous  modifications  in  the  interplay  of  dif- 
ferent personalities.  All  this  does  not  suggest  that  formally  allocated  author- 
ity amounts  to  little.  It  does  suggest  that  it  is  never  quite  the  same  as 
circumstances  alter. 

Forms  of  Personal  Organization.  We  have  earlier  alluded  to  the  phe- 
nomenon of  personal  organization — special  structures  of  relationships  built 
freely  for  the  convenience  of  individual  leaders  within  the  formal  framework 
of  the  organization.  The  members  of  a  personal  organization  may  not 
always  be  identified  as  such  except  to  the  inner  circle  they  represent.  Their 
individual  roles  will  vary,  too.  On  the  level  of  the  top  executive,  for  in- 
stance, some  members  will  be  primarily  sources  of  confidential  information. 
Others  may  be  placed  strategically  for  the  stimulation  of  prompt  response 
to  administrative  directives  from  above;  these  members  of  the  top  executive's 
personal  organization  are  to  "carry  the  ball"  for  him  in  the  sphere  of  opera-, 
tions.  While  functioning  for  the  most  part  independently  and  at  different 
points  of  the  hierarchical  structure,  all  members  will  maintain  contact  with 
one  another  as  well  as  with  "the  chief."  They  will  act  in  concert,  though 
for  best  effect  their  synchronized  action  usually  retains  the  appearance  of 
coincidence  and  spontaneity. 

The  existence  of  such  personal  organizations  formed  around  individual 
exponents  of  control — the  department  head,  chiefs  of  larger  staff  or  auxiliary 
services,  line  officers  on  various  levels  of  command,  and  even  unit  supervi- 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  301 

sors  at  the  base  of  operations—in  itself  attests  to  the  limitations  of  formal 
authority.  Power  of  direction  may  be  commensurate  with  personal  respon- 
sibility at  each  control  point  of  the  administrative  hierarchy,  yet  direction 
does  not  automatically  elicit  positive  response.  All  large-scale  organization, 
because  of  both  its  size  and  its  specialization,  is  highly  vulnerable  to  internal 
indifference,  intransigence,  and  obstruction.  Left  to  himself,  even  the  top 
executive,  in  the  imposing  plenitude  of  his  directive  power,  may  have  the 
ugly  feeling  of  perching  atop  an  angry  elephant  firmly  set  to  have  things 
his  own  way.  True  enough,  the  executive  has  his  "arms  of  management" — 
administrative  planning,  budgeting,  personnel — and  his  line  subleadership 
to  rely  upon.  But  how  much  of  this  supporting  cast  can  be  trusted  actually 
to  support  him? 

How  real  this  question  is  can  perhaps  be  seen  most  readily  when  we 
think  of  a  new  appointee  taking  over  a  government  department.  This  may 
be  an  entirely  novel  experience  for  him,  as  it  usually  is.  There  is  no  one 
to  brief  him  on  his  first  day  of  office.  He  is  lucky  if  he  knows  one  or  two 
key  people  in  the  department  sufficiently  well  to  be  sure  of  their  sym- 
pathetic help  right  at  the  start,  and  some  others  against  whom  he  should 
be  on  guard.  He  may  be  free  to  bring  along  a  small  number  of  personal 
assistants — each  probably  as  green  at  the  start  on  departmental  business 
as  he  himself.  Replacements  in  the  top  range  of  command  will  have  to 
wait  until  the  new  head  has  had  time  to  reach  more  or  less  final  judg- 
ments on  the  internal  situation  he  is  facing. 

His  first  thought  in  testing  personalities  he  has  to  depend  upon  will  be 
to  have  assurance  of  their  complete  loyalty  so  that  he  in  turn  can  have  full 
confidence  in  them  and  talk  to  them  without  mental  reservations.  Because 
too  many  new  appointments  would  mean  a  heavy  mortgage  of  inexperience, 
he  is  never  free  to  fire  and  hire  at  will,  quite  aside  from  the  limitations 
placed  upon  him  by  the  civil  service  system.  In  the  main,  he  must  learn 
to  work  with  the  department  as  he  finds  it,  and  teafh  his  immediate  sub- 
ordinates to  take  to  him  and  work  with  him.  In  some  instances  he  will  be 
able  to  shift  individual  officers  he  spots  as  congenial  into  positions  in  his 
proximity.  As  a  general  rule,  however,  he  has  only  a  restricted  opportunity 
for  rearranging  the  human  pattern  around  him.  ^ 

In  the  experience  of  his  first  few  months,  he  will  therefore  attempt  to 
create  his  own  unofficial  peerage  from  within  the  department.  He  will  turn 
repeatedly  to  those  who  win  his  confidence  first.  These  will  become  con- 
scious of  their  task  as  intermediaries,  and  in  due  course  will  be  treated  and 
used  as  such  by  their  colleagues.  Unofficial  peers  can  be  made  and  unmade 
by  the  department  head;  readjustments  in  the  structure  of  his  peerage  may 
happen  rather  frequently  at  the  beginning,  and  will  continue  to  occur  at 
later  periods.  Slowly,  however,  a  degree  of  constancy  will  evolve  in  his 
personal  organization.  At  best,  its  constancy  will  allow  for  a  recognition 
of  those  special  talents  which  are  at  a  premium  in  this  kind  of  grouping. 


302  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

One  of  those  rare  individuals  who  have  a  good  grasp  of  the  department 
as  a  whole— perhaps  the  budget  officer,  perhaps  a  bureau  chief  with  many 
years  of  service  and  a  sufficient  variety  of  successive  responsibilities  behind 
him— is  likely  to  be  drawn  into  the  personal  organization  of  the  top  execu- 
tive. His  personal  assistants  brought  by  him  into  the  department  become 
"charter  members,"  though  not  necessarily  for  all  time  to  come.  It  would 
be  erroneous  to  assume  that  every  one  of  the  political  officeholders  of  the 
department  is  simultaneously  a  member  of  the  peerage  in  our  sense.  One 
of  them  may  be  too  intimately  tied  into  a  powerful  interest  group  that  eyes 
the  department  head  with  misapprehension.  Another  may  remain  too  much 
adrift  in  the  affairs  of  the  department  to  win  standing  within  it.  On  the 
other  hand,  some  of  the  permanent  officials  will  be  included  in  the  top 
executive's  personal  organization  because  of  their  strength  as  leaders,  be- 
cause of  the  multiplicity  of  their  working  contacts  with  others,  or  because 
of  their  range  of  practical  experience.  In  addition,  his  personal  organization 
is  apt  to  reach  into  such  highly  sensitive  functions  as  public  relations^ 
legislative  liaison,  and  field  direction. 

Objective  qualifications  alone  are  never  enough  for  membership;  above 
such  qualifications,  the  decisive  factor  is  a  substantial  degree  of  personal 
compatibility  with  the  intellectual  approach  and  the  outlook  of  the  depart- 
ment head.  His  personal  organization  is  basically  made  up  of  "king's  men," 
whether  as  a  tight  group  or  as  a  loose  affiliation.  Within  it,  stars  may  rise 
and  fall.  There  may  also  be  occasional  cases  of  desertion.  Moreover,  his 
personal  organization  is  never  the  only  one.  For  greatest  utility  it  must  link 
itself  to  the  personal  organizations  developed  by  ranking  subordinate  lead- 
ers. Where  a  subordinate  leader  differentiates  himself  from  the  fortunes  of 
the  department  head,  the  latter's  personal  organization  must  attempt  to 
outmaneuver  or  to  checkmate  in  one  or  another  form  the  "king's  men"  of 
the  uncooperative  subordinate.  Prolonged  battles  may  rage  between  dif- 
ferent personal  organizations.  Formal  agreements  in  open  conference  may 
in  many  cases  be  merely  the  product  of  informal  bargains  for  support.  The 
price  exacted  for  such  support  may  be  an  important  promotion,  an  enlarge- 
ment of  functions,  or  a  greater  degree  of  independence  in  specified  areas. 
Such  concessions  may  interfere  with  general  expectancies  based  on  official 
rules  and  customs,  causing  losses  in  morale  throughout  the  department. 
There  is  hence  always  a  point  of  declining  returns. 

Yet  it  is  clear  that  without  this  type  of  personal  organization,  individual 
leaders  in  the  department  cannot  hope  to  know  what  is  really  going  on, 
what  the  attitudes  of  the  working  force  are,  and  how  to  generate  momen- 
tum for  cooperative  action  in  the  sphere  of  their  own  concerns.  Teamwork 
is  not  achieved  by  mere  pronouncement  of  hierarchical  superiors.  It  re- 
quires recognition  of  the  most  accomplished  players  on  each  team.  Indeed, 
one  or  two  of  these  may  monopolize  the  actual  leadership  in  the  team, 
leaving  the  nominal  leader  in  the  role  of  a  figurehead.  At  the  same  time, 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  303 

it  is  obvious  that  effective  personal  organization  calls  for  much  adroit  han- 
dling, and  much  mature  appreciation  of  relationships,  coupled  with  a  sense 
of  reality.  As  with  organization  in  the  formal  sense,  personal  organization 
may  easily  militate  against  itself.  It  may  become  a  burden  on  the  individual 
leader,  setting  him  off  from  his  wider  institutional  environment.  It  may 
inject  elements  of  arbitrariness  or  favoritism  into  general  working  processes. 
It  may  substitute  subjective  considerations  for  objective  evaluations,  dis- 
rupting the  regularity  of  operations  and  destroying  the  promise  of 
planned  advancement  toward  acknowledged  aims. 

The  balance  sheet  of  personal  organization  has  its  debit  as  well  as  its 
credit  side.  On  the  debit  side  we  would  have  to  enter  the  possibility  of 
doubts  seeping  through  the  department  about  the  integrity  of  management, 
soundness  of  decisions,  and  justice  in  internal  allocation  of  rewards.  Per- 
sonal organization  can  be  a  great  convenience  in  attaining  impersonal 
objectives — policy  goals.  It  can  also  acquire  the  characteristics  of  personal 
government  and  thus  corrupt  impersonal  objectives.  An  able  department 
head  will  periodically  examine  the  balance  sheet— and  draw  his  own  prac- 
tical conclusions. 

Ties  of  Allegiance.  Formal  organization  suggests  a  monolithic  structure 
in  which  all  wills  are  bent  toward  a  defined  set  of  institutional  goals.  Ac- 
ceptance of  these  goals  is  at  least  implicit  throughout  the  entire  structure. 
An  outstanding  leader  at  the  helm  of  the  organization  may  not  only  be- 
come a  symbolic  expression  of  the  validity  and  continuity  of  acknowledged 
objectives  but  he  may  also  draw  forth  the  allegiance  of  his  subleadership 
and  with  it  that  of  the  large  body  of  personnel.  I  Even  then,  however,  there 
remain  in  each  individual  certain  residual  allegiances  of  varying  strength 
that  exert  their  pulls  in  different  directions.5  Man  is  only  in  part  organize 
able.  He  lives  only  in  part  in  his  occupation.  The  fanatic  alone  is  able  to 
pour  all  of  his  capacity  for  allegiance  into  a  single  cause. 

Normally,  every  individual  responds  to  a  wide  range  of  loyalties — some 
embedded  in  his  background,  some  foisted  upon  him  in  the  school  of  living, 
some  freely  accepted  as  a  matter  of  deliberate  choice.  In  this  agglomeration 
no  single  loyalty  will  dominate  all  others.  For  satisfying  human  experience, 
however,  all  such  loyalties  should  admit  of  harmonious  blending  without 
contradiction  or  conflict.  The  same  applies  to  man  as  part  of  an  organiza- 
tion in  which  he  spends  his  occupational  life.  No  more  can  be  expected 
of  him  than  that  the  total  fabric  of  his  loyalties  keep  him  receptive  to  the 
goals  of  the  organization  he  is  serving.  Yet,  notwithstanding  a  general 
accord  of  loyalties,  each  loyalty  separately  continues  to  have  some  influence 
upon  him.  Each  loyalty,  depending  on  the  circumstances,  may  place  him 
in  part  or  for  a  time  in  juxtaposition  to  the  organization  for  which  he 
works. 


5  For  an  illuminating  discussion  of  the  complex  pattern  of  civic  allegiances,  see  Merriam, 
Charles  £.,  The  Making  of  Citizens,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1931. 


304  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

This  is  the  basic  reason  why  institutional  leadership  must  constantly 
attempt  to  magnify  individual  loyalty  toward  the  institution.  Such  effort 
cannot  be  confined  to  a  single  approach — a  single  "morale  program."  It 
must  come  to  the  fore  in  everything  the  organization  undertakes  to  ac- 
complish. To  foster  what  military  language  calls  "pride  of  outfit,"  institu- 
tional leadership  must  be  articulate  and  persuasive  on  its  objectives  and  poli- 
cies, adept  in  developing  a  general  system  of  internal  incentives,  resourceful 
in  broadening  the  base  for  individual  participation  in  determining  the  ends 
and  means  of  the  organization,  and  inventive  in  distributing  credit  for 
collective  accomplishment. 

While  formal  authority  rests  axiomatically  on  universal  recognition  of 
deference  owed  it,  no  assurance  exists  that  loyalty  will  conform  to  institut- 
tional  assumptions.  Even  in  reasonably  homogeneous  organizations  capable 
of  producing  a  common  feeling  of  institutional  individuality  and  identity, 
each  member  may  stand  in  a  different  relationship  to  the  organization  as 
a  whole.  Some  members  may  completely  give  themselves  to  the  organiza- 
tion, regarding  it  as  their  better"  part.  Others  may  accept  institutional 
authority  as  a  pragmatic  compromise  essential  to  their  cooperative  role  in  the 
organization.  Still  others  may  be  satisfied  with  a  more  passive  attitude — 
"live  and  let  live"— while  reserving  their  deeper  attachments  for  private 
pursuits  outside  the  organization.  Finally,  there  will  be  those  who,  though 
not  necessarily  antagonistic  to  the  organization  itself,  will  strive  to  super- 
impose on  the  "powers  to  be"  values  derived  from  loyalties  other  than  that 
demanded  by  the  organization. 

Such  competing  loyalties  may  have  external  or  internal  focus;  often  both 
types  are  intermingled  imperceptibly.  Under  the  external  rubric,  for  exam- 
ple, we  may  think  of  a  bureau  chief  who  has  driven  such  firm  roots  into 
the  function  entrusted  to  his  bureau  that  he  consciously  or  unconsciously 
reflects  in  all  his  thinking  the  preferences  of  the  outside  interest  group  which 
looks  upon  this  function  with  proprietary  eyes.  He  has  wholly  equated 
his  responsibility  with  the  ends  pursued  by  the  interest  group.  If  anywhere 
challenged  by  his  official  superiors,  he  does  not  hesitate  to  plot  his  defense 
in  closed  session  with  the  chieftains  of  the  interest  group.  These  may  make 
him  feel  like  a  central  figure  in  their  councils,  run  personal  publicity  for  him, 
and  build  him  up  as  a  great  public  servant  or  a  national  expert.  Blind  to 
more  general  objectives,  he  comes  to  consider  his  superiors  as  evil  forces 
against  which  he  must  battle  tenaciously  in  order  to  guard  the  function  of 
his  bureau — and  the  outside  interest  that  supports  it  and  him  alike. 

Or  we  may  think  of  an  assistant  secretary  in  a  department  whose  creden- 
tials for  public  service  stem  from  earlier  political  affiliation  with  a  legislative 
bloc  that  because  of  its  aims  inevitably  impinges  upon  the  department.  His 
official  chief  may  deal  with  him  as  if  he  were— as  he  essentially  is— a  hostile 
observer  posted  for  sniping,  missing  no  chance  of  capitalizing  on  his  legisla- 
tive support  in  order  to  further  the  purposes  of  the  legislative  bloc.  Every 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  305 

it  is  obvious  that  effective  personal  organization  calls  for  much  adroit  han- 
dling, and  much  mature  appreciation  of  relationships,  coupled  with  a  sense 
of  reality.  As  with  organization  in  the  formal  sense,  personal  organization 
may  easily  militate  against  itself.  It  may  become  a  burden  on  the  individual 
leader,  setting  him  off  from  his  wider  institutional  environment.  It  may 
inject  elements  of  arbitrariness  or  favoritism  into  general  working  processes. 
It  may  substitute  subjective  considerations  for  objective  evaluations,  dis- 
rupting the  regularity  of  operations  and  destroying  the  promise  of 
planned  advancement  toward  acknowledged  aims. 

The  balance  sheet  of  personal  organization  has  its  debit  as  well  as  its 
credit  side.  On  the  debit  side  we  would  have  to  enter  the  possibility  of 
doubts  seeping  through  the  department  about  the  integrity  of  management, 
soundness  of  decisions,  and  justice  in  internal  allocation  of  rewards.  Per- 
sonal organization  can  be  a  great  convenience  in  attaining  impersonal 
objectives — policy  goals.  It  can  also  acquire  the  characteristics  of  personal 
government  and  thus  corrupt  impersonal  objectives.  An  able  department 
head  will  periodically  examine  the  balance  sheet — and  draw  his  own  prac- 
tical conclusions. 

Ties  of  Allegiance.  Formal  organization  suggests  a  monolithic  structure 
in  which  all  wills  are  bent  toward  a  defined  set  of  institutional  goals.  Ac- 
ceptance of  these  goals  is  at  least  implicit  throughout  the  entire  structure. 
An  outstanding  leader  at  the  helm  of  the  organization  may  not  only  be- 
come a  symbolic  expression  of  the  validity  and  continuity  of  acknowledged 
objectives  but  he  may  also  draw  forth  the  allegiance  of  his  subleadership 
and  with  it  that  of  the  large  body  of  personnel.  J  Even  then,  however,  there 
remain  in  each  individual  certain  residual  allegiances  of  varying  strength 
that  exert  their  pulls  in  different  directions.5  Man  is  only  in  part  organize 
able.  He  lives  only  in  part  in  his  occupation.  The  fanatic  alone  is  able  to 
pour  all  of  his  capacity  for  allegiance  into  a  single  cause. 

Normally,  every  individual  responds  to  a  wide  range  of  loyalties — some 
embedded  in  his  background,  some  foisted  upon  him  in  the  school  of  living, 
some  freely  accepted  as  a  matter  of  deliberate  choice.  In  this  agglomeration 
no  single  loyalty  will  dominate  all  others.  For  satisfying  human  experience, 
however,  all  such  loyalties  should  admit  of  harmonious  blending  without 
contradiction  or  conflict.  The  same  applies  to  man  as  part  of  an  organiza- 
tion in  which  he  spends  his  occupational  life.  No  more  can  be  expected 
of  him  than  that  the  total  fabric  of  his  loyalties  keep  him  receptive  to  the 
goals  of  the  organization  he  is  serving.  Yet,  notwithstanding  a  general 
accord  of  loyalties,  each  loyalty  separately  continues  to  have  some  influence 
upon  him.  Each  loyalty,  depending  on  the  circumstances,  may  place  him 
in  part  or  for  a  time  in  juxtaposition  to  the  organization  for  which  he 
works. 


5  For  an  illuminating  discussion  of  the  complex  pattern  of  civic  allegiances,  see  Merriam, 
Charles  £.,  The  Making  of  Citizens,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1931. 


306  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

other  lawyers;  an  engineer  dealing  with  lawyers  may  gravitate  instinctively 
toward  support  of  the  views  of  other  engineers.  Or,  in  questions  of  func- 
tional grouping  and  allocation  of  responsibilities,  individual  categories  of 
specialists  may  predicate  their  opinions  primarily  on  their  conception  of  the 
stake  of  their  specialty  in  the  proposed  arrangement. 

In  addition,  personal  association  of  a  comparable  character — with  cor- 
responding investment  of  loyalty — may  spring  from  common  backgrounds. 
Graduation  from  the  same  college  or  professional  school  is  one  illustration; 
earlier  staff  experience  in  the  same  scientific  foundation  or  research  institu- 
tion or  consulting  firm  is  another.  Like  any  other  type  of  large-scale  organi- 
zation, moreover,  government  departments  have  their  ideological  factions — 
here  the  "liberals,"  there  the  "conservatives."  Eager  stalwarts  of  each  fac- 
tion are  likely  to  look  at  the  department  as  a  potential  area  of  conquest,  or 
at  least  an  object  of  proportionate  influence.  Factional  struggles  may  not 
always  be  conspicuous,  but  the  sense  of  loyalty  produced  in  their  heat  may 
leave  little  loyalty  to  the  department  itself.  Finally,  we  should  mention  the 
ties  of  allegiance  among  the  organized  rank  and  file  of  employees.  The 
locals  of  government-employee  unions  may  attract  to  themselves  a  substan- 
tial share  of  loyalty,  especially  in  the  face  of  an  unsympathetic  or  laggard 
departmental  leadership. 

Thus  the  actual  pattern  of  human  relationships  and  allegiances  within 
the  formal  organization  is  distinguished  by  obvious  complexity.  Reference 
to  "channels  of  command"  may  becloud  the  real  picture.  Uncrowned  lead- 
ers compete  with  crowned  ones.  Informal  and  often  unaccountable  group- 
ings brought  to  life  for  various  purposes  press  against  one  another.  Nor  are 
the  underlying  motivations  always  either  clear  or  durable.  Human  beings 
freely  exercise  their  privilege  to  change  their  minds  on  what  seems  worth 
their  effort.  So  does  man  in  organization.  This  explains  in  part  why  any 
given  organization  may  demonstrate  great  vigor  at  certain  times  and  may 
virtually  fall  apart  or  drop  into  a  coma  at  certain  other  times,  even  though 
its  general  mandate  or  its  formal  structure  remain  unchanged.  It  also  casts 
a  sharp  light  on  the  folly  of  considering  a  department  a  mighty  steamroller 
pursuing  its  aims  with  mechanical  precision.  Last  but  not  least,  it  shows 
how  much  we  borrow  from  imagination  when  we  talk  about  the  sinister 
designs  of  a  single-minded  bureaucracy. 

3.    NONHIERARCHICAL  SOURCES  OF  POWER 

Democratic  theory  stresses  the  unregimented  evolution  of  free  associa- 
tions of  citizens  who  can  raise  their  voices  politically  and  speak  for  them- 
selves. The  very  diversity  of  these  associations  is  justly  considered  an  asset 
to  democratic  governance.  Public  preferences  can  be  tested  in  open  argu- 
ment. Fresh  ideas  can  find  direct  and  immediate  expression.  Workable 
compromises  can  be  forged  in  the  adjustment  of  group  aims  to  one  an- 
other. This,  we  feel,  is  the  soundest  way  of  tapping  and  mobilizing  the 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  307 

political  resources  of  the  whole  nation.  Even  those  who  occasionally  doubt 
the  productivity  of  too  much  diffusion  and  too  much  milling  movement 
on  the  political  scene  would  be  very  reluctant  to  sacrifice  the  values  of  un- 
impaired self-expression  to  a  superimposed  "order"  that  would  choke  group 
autonomy  under  a  gigantic  blanket  of  directed  uniformity.  But  free  politi- 
cal competition  is  not  without  pitfalls.  It  may  operate  to  the  detriment  of 
the  public  interest.  There  is  a  great  difference  between  the  National  League 
of  Women  Voters  and  an  economic  pressure  group  whose  voting  strength 
or  financial  support  may  in  effect  corner  much  of  the  political  mar- 
ket.7 It  is  all  too  evident  that  pressure  politics  may  degenerate  into  brash 
hijacking. 

Informal  organization  offers  some  close  parallels.  Unless  confined  in 
both  scope  and  form,  it  may  turn  into  a  disorganizing  force,  undoing  at 
least  in  part  what  formal  organization  is  intended  to  achieve.  It  may  dan- 
gerously widen  the  cracks  and  crannies  which  division  of  labor  and  segre- 
gation of  functions  inevitably  tears  into  the  structure  of  all  formal  organi- 
zatioijA  It  may  in  certain  areas  actually  nullify  official  responsibility.  With 
all  that,  informal  organization  does  meet  practical  needs.  Like  the  free  in- 
terplay of  democratic  groups  in  the  civic  realm,  it  is  in  many  respects  a 
source  of  administrative  vitality.  It  provides  additional  outlets  for  group 
opinion,  thus  extending  and  broadening  the  avenues  of  institutional  plan- 
ning and  thought.  Informal  leadership,  moreover,  is  in  a  sense  as  much 
a  school  of  responsibility  as  the  exercise  of  official  authority.  In  short,  in- 
formal organization,  aside  from  being  a  perfectly  natural  growth,  not  only 
to  some  extent  eases  the  rigidities  of  hierarchy  but  also  can  work  as  a  desir- 
able stimulant  to  a  timid  or  uninspired  top  command.Y  How  far  it  does 
the  latter  will  depend  mainly  on  the  public  spirit  of  its  leaders.  ^ 

This  may  become  clearer  through  a  more  specific  review  of  some  com- 
posite pictures  of  fairly  typical  manifestations  of  informal  organization. 
Each  manifestation  is  selected  at  random,  without  any  attempt  at  complete- 
ness of  display.  But  all  have  one  feature  in  common:  they  demonstrate 
nonhierarchical  sources  of  power.  That  is  to  say,  they  show  concrete  points 
.  of  influence  that  are  separate  from  the  structure  of  hierarchical  power,  even 
though  in  some  instances  they  are  related  to  the  location  of  formal  authority. 

Men  Behind  the  Throne.  As  no  ruler— be  he  an  omnipotent  dictator 
or  a  constitutional  president — thinks  and  acts  in  splendid  isolation,  as  there 
are  always  men  and  women  in  his  entourage  who  intentionally  or  uninten- 
tionally help  him  to  make  up  his  mind,8  so  the  head  of  a  government  de- 
partment, however  retiring  and  introvert  by  nature,  is  surrounded  by  his 
"inner  circle."  He  may  have  a  regular  "cabinet"  of  his  own,  made  up  pcr- 

7  Sec  below  Ch.  14,  "Interest  Groups  in  Administration,"  sec.  1,  "The  Meaning  of  Interest 
Representation." 

8  For  a  penetrating  discussion,  long  overlooked,  see  Bentley,  Arthur  F.,  The  Process  of 
Government,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1908;  republished  Bloomington:  Principia 
Press,  1935. 


308  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

haps  of  his  principal  staff  and  line  officers,  with  whom  he  discusses  matters 
of  general  importance  at  a  set  hour  each  week  or  oftener.  On  special  issues 
he  may  confer  with  smaller  or  larger  groups  of  officials,  excluding  those 
members  of  his  cabinet  not  directly  concerned,  and  drawing  in  other  officers 
who  do  not  ordinarily  attend  the  cabinet  meetings.  Consultative  organs  of 
some  kind  are  an  administrative  necessity;  whether  they  are  always  intel- 
ligently utilized  is  still  another  question.9  However,  the  existence  of  such 
machinery  seldom  gives  a  hint  about  the  way  in  which  the  top  executive 
frames  his  judgments.  He  may  be  merely  a  polite  listener.  He  may  simply 
believe  such  formally  organized  consultation  to  be  a  proper  democratic 
gesture.  Or  he  may  use  his  cabinet  meetings  primarily  as  a  method  of 
communicating  his  decisions  to  the  first  level  of  his  subleadership.  How, 
then,  does  he  reach  his  decisions? 

It  is  at  this  point  only  that  we  turn  from  formal  organization  to  in- 
formal one.  The  insider  may  tell  us  that  the  cabinet  is  just  a  ritual;  that 
there  is  in  fact  something  like  an  "inner  cabinet"  of  only  three  members; 
and  that  one  of  these  is  not  even  included  in  the  official  cabinet.  Those  in 
the  inner  cabinet  are  the  "men  behind  the  throne."  The  one  who  does  not 
belong  to  the  official  cabinet  is  the  senior  personal  assistant  to  the  depart- 
ment head.  For  many  years  he  has  been  the  political  shadow  of  the  man 
who  now  directs  the  affairs  of  the  department — a  relationship  that  developed 
long  ago  in  local  politics  and  has  been  reinforced  in  the  test  of  changing 
fortunes  as  both  made  their  way  within  the  currently  dominant  major 
party.  This  personal  assistant  has  no  clearly  defined  functions.  He  is  r 
Colonel  House  or  a  Harry  Hopkins  to  the  department  head.  Moreover,  he 
is  the  department's  most  important  liaison  to  the  party  leadership  and  tht 
legislative  body  as  well.  He  and  "the  chief"  have  come  to  think  as  one 
nind.  The  other  two  members  of  the  inner  cabinet  are  one  of  the  assist- 
ant secretaries  and  a  bureau  chief.  The  assistant  secretary  is  the  youngest 
man  on  the  top  level,  but  he  has  proved  himself  an  invaluable  fountain 
of  fertile  ideas.  That  is  the  reason  why  he  overshadows  the  undersecretary, 
who  is  weighted  down  by  a  heavy  burden  of  operating  responsibilities.  The 
bureau  chief  is  known  neither  for  imaginative  thinking  nor  for  good 
political  judgment.  However,  he  has  been  with  the  department  for  nearly 
two  decades  and  he  knows  its  practical  business  inside  out. 

It  is  with  these  three  men  that  the  department  head  arrives  at  his  deci- 
sions, sometimes  at  a  tray  luncheon  in  his  office,  sometimes  during  a  brief 
session  preceding  a  meeting  of  his  cabinet.  Because  all  four  know  each 
other  very  closely,  they  are  able  to  express  themselves  in  some  kind  of  short- 
hand language,  coming  to  the  point  in  a  few  words.  There  is  not  only 
extraordinary  economy  in  their  method  of  oral  communication,  but  each 
is  also  fully  aware  of  every  one  else's  general  bias,  including  his  own.  This 

9  Cf.  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "Bureaucracy  and  Consultation,"  Review  of  Politics,  1939,  Vol. 
1,  p.  84  ff. 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  309 

introduces  desirable  checks.  On  the  other  hand,  their  joint  consultations 
often  end  merely  in  preliminary  determinations— what  sort  of  study  to  call 
for  by  the  administrative-management  unit;  whom  to  ask  for  further  in- 
formation; what  kind  of  fact-finding  to  set  in  motion.  Thus  this  group  of 
four  is  linked  to  the  hierarchy  to  the  extent  that  it  jointly  exercises  the  ex- 
ecutive function.  However,  the  status  of  the  three  members  of  the  inner 
cabinet  is  as  unofficial  and  informal  as  the  department  head's  personal  or- 
ganization, which  may  be  much  larger  in  size  and  may  overlap  his  official 
cabinet  only  in  small  part. 

The  type  of  consultative  grouping  here  portrayed  resembles  a  regency, 
with  the  king  withdrawing,  for  all  practical  purposes,  into  the  role  of  one 
member.  In  other  comparable  institutional  situations,  the  "men  behind  the 
throne"  may  be  an  equally  small  body  of  departmental  elder  statesmen  with 
or  without  actual  veto  power;  or  a  more  fluid  group  of  little  collective 
strength,  throwing  the  greatest  influence  in  the  direction  of  the  subordi- 
nate with  whom  the  department  head  happened  to  talk  last.  It  must  be 
doubted  whether  there  is  a  single  "best  way"  of  organizing  and  using  the 
"men  behind  the  throne."  The  decisive  factor  will  often  be  the  working 
habits  of  the  top  executive.  In  such  small  groups,  of  course,  it  is  highly 
advantageous  that  each  individual  member  consciously  complement  the 
abilities  and  inclinations  of  the  other  members.  The  greatest  peril  lies 
in  the  possibility  that  the  convenience  of  harmony  reduces  the  group's  ca- 
pacity for  criticism;  after  all,  life  is  much  more  agreeable  when  one  can 
roll  along  under  the  momentum  supplied  by  the  strongest  personality.  It 
is  also  obvious  that  much  tact  and  ingenuity  is  required  of  each  member 
of  the  group  in  minimizing  the  importance  of  his  informal  function  in 
his  dealings  with  the  hierarchy  itself,  and  in  respecting  openly  all  the 
proprieties  of  internal  authority. 

The  Personal  Secretary.  Throughout  the  administrative  hierarchy,  indi- 
vidual key  men  would  in  most  instances  cut  sorry  figures  were  it  not  for 
the  untiring  assistance  they  receive  from  their  personal  secretaries.  As  the 
housekeeper  of  the  administrative  estate  of  her  boss,  the  personal  secretary 
may  feel  herself  to  be  part  of  the  structure  of  authority.  Outside  the  insti- 
tutional province  of  her  boss,  her  importance  is  frequently  underrated; 
inside  she  may  be  treated  like  a  queen.  Her  responsibilities  reflect  those  of 
the  boss;  and  within  certain  limitations  she  may  even  act  as  his  alter  ego. 
As  the  stenographic  manual  of  one  federal  agency  explains: 

To  be  a  real  help  to  the  executive,  she  must  know  how  he  would  like 
to  have  a  task  performed  and  do  it  that  way.  She  must  be  alert  to  grasp 
situations  and  draw  sound  conclusions,  to  take  into  consideration  more 
than  meets  the  eye  or  the  ear.  She  must  be  able  to  follow  the  wishes  of 
her  chief,  even  to  anticipate  them. 

.  .  .  The  "thinking  secretary"  proves  her  ability  to  take  responsibility; 
to  express  initiative,  originality,  and  resourcefulness.  This  thoughtful 


310  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

attitude  is  the  basis  for  judgment,  which  is  essential  in  tempering  all 
other  traits. 

An  extremely  important  point  for  the  secretary  to  remember  is  that 
she  represents  both  her  chief  and  the  agency  to  callers,  in  person  and  over 
the  telephone.  She  must  put  herself  in  her  chief's  place  and  convey  the 
impression  and  the  information  as  he  would  have  her  do  it.  ...  Besides 
a  thorough  knowledge  of  the  facts  in  the  case,  this  often  requires  cour- 
tesy and  tact.  Since  the  executive  and  his  secretary  function  interde- 
pendently,  it  is  particularly  important  that  they  have  a  complete 
understanding  about  telephone  practices  so  that  all  calls  will  be  taken 
care  of  adequately  in  a  manner  appropriate  to  the  agency.  The  secretary 
must  see  that  all  calls  are  followed  through  to  completion  or  returned 
promptly,  as  dictated  by  courtesy. 

The  secretary  must  become  skillful  in  taking  interruptions  herself  and 
in  interrupting  others.  She  must  determine  when  something  is  suf- 
ficiently important  or  urgent  to  justify  interrupting  her  chief  at  a  con- 
ference and  the  method  by  which  she  will  convey  the  message  to  him, 
remembering  that  she  interrupts  not  only  her  chief  but  others  as  well. 

Because  the  boss  himself  generally  occupies  a  dual  position  as  an  ex- 
ponent of  the  official  hierarchy  and  as  a  member  of  one  or  more  informal 
organizations,  his  personal  secretary  must  extend  her  activities  in  these  same 
different  directions.  Her  main  stock  in  trade  is  knowledge  of  things  that 
only  her  boss  knows.  Only  she  can  tell  where  he  is  at  the  moment,  whether 
he  may  be  accessible  "for  a  few  minutes"  during  the  next  few  hours, 
where  the  memorandum  now  is  that  was  sent  up  to  him  day  before  yester- 
day, what  matters  are  still  on  his  desk,  what  disposition  he  is  likely  to  make 
of  each  matter.  In  giving  information  of  this  kind,  in  arranging  the  list  of 
callers  and  conferences,  in  adjusting  priority  among  appointments  as 
urgencies  change,  in  drawing  the  attention  of  her  boss  to  items  that  have 
passed  from  his  mind — in  all  of  her  activities  she  must  be  thoroughly  cog- 
nizant of  the  specific  character  of  the  relationship  between  him  and  others. 

She  must  have  a  sure  sense  of  differentiation;  some  demands  on  the  time 
of  her  boss  need  to  be  rebuffed,  while  on  others  she  will  yield  with  ease. 
Members  of  his  own  personal  organization  may  share  with  her  confidential 
information  that  she  would  never  think  of  disclosing  to  any  one  except 
other  members  of  the  personal  organization.  Indeed,  she  may  become  the 
manager  of  the  agenda  for  this  personal  organization.  She  must  make  it  her 
business  to  hear  and  to  see — drawing  even  from  the  gossip  of  the  office 
and  the  cafeteria  hints  and  suggestions  of  profit  to  her  boss.  Through  her 
contacts  with  other  secretaries,  she  may  become  a  special  channel  of  intelli- 
gence to  other  kinds  of  informal  organization. 

Small  wonder  that  the  personal  secretary  will  often  know  her  boss  better 
than  docs  his  wife.  He  may  find  it  of  benefit  to  pose  to  her  administrative 
problems  to  which  he  has  no  ready  answer.  He  may  leave  her  a  great  deal 
of  discretion  in  handling  particular  matters  with  his  subordinates.  He  will 
feel  hopelessly  stranded  when  a  cold  keeps  her  from  the  office.  Others 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  311 

working  for  him  will  soon  learn  the  importance  of  approaching  him 
through  her.  They  will  also  respect  her  as  an  astute  judge  of  their  stake 
in  any  given  matter.  They  will  try  to  gain  her  favor,  but  she  would  not  be 
able  to  conduct  her  business  with  full  efficiency  if  she  proved  an  easy 
victim  of  flattery. 

The  Invincible  Constellation.  In  our  discussion  of  informal  groupings 
we  have  noticed  time  and  again  the  extent  to  which  in  administrative  insti- 
tutions— as  in  all  large-scale  enterprise10 — the  hierarchical  order  of  authority 
is  modified  by  the  factor  of  personal  standing  within  the  organization.  This 
is  true  also  within  the  hierarchy  itself.  There  are  everywhere  individuals  on 
a  relatively  lower  level  of  authority  who  "count"  and  thus  overshadow 
others  on  a  higher  level  of  authority.  For  example,  a  ranking  staff  officer 
may  belong  to  the  department  head's  official  cabinet,  and  yet  he  may  not 
"count."  Or  a  line  executive  may  be  entitled  to  all  the  vestments  of 
seniority,  and  yet  he  knows  that  his  opinions  and  proposals  find  no  takers 
unless  they  are  endorsed  by  some  one  who  does  "count."  Conversely,  those 
within  a  department  who  are  familiar  with  the  structure  of  informal  organi- 
zation will  be  able  to  point  to  four  or  five  unadvertised  officials  whose 
agreement  on  any  matter  is  tantamount  to  a  departmental  decision. 
Those  are  the  few  one  has  to  see  in  order  to  get  action — the  "invincible 
constellation." 

The  informal  status  of  the  members  of  this  cardinal  group  may  have 
quite  different  foundations.  One  may  be  a  central  figure  in  the  top  execu- 
tive's personal  organization.  Another  may  be  the  action-man  among  those 
"behind  the  throne."  No  less  often  will  membership  in  the  "invincible 
constellation"  rest  on  a  firmly  established  reputation  for  soundness  in  judging 
the  feasibility  and  efficacy  of  proposed  action.  This  is  sometimes  a  matter 
of  breadth  of  appreciation  of  all  the  factors  that  may  affect  specific  meas- 
ures— an  attribute  of  precise  thinking  and  rich  experience.  Equally  often 
such  reputation  may  simply  stem  from  the  fact  that  luckily  previous  judg- 
ments have  usually  proved  right  rather  than  wrong.  Whatever  the  source 
of  the  glory  of  infallibility,  the  fact  remains  that  the  initials  of  these  four 


10  Study  of  informal  organization  is  still  in  its  infancy.  Valuable  insights  were  furnished 
indirectly  by  Bentley,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  8.  More  specific  materials  can  be  found  in 
Mayo,  Elton,  Human  Problems  of  an  Industrial  Civilization,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1933; 
Barnard,  Chester  I.,  The  Functions  of  the  Executive,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press, 
1938,  rcpublished  1945;  Tead,  Ordway,  Human  Nature  and  Management,  New  York: 
McGraw-Hill,  1933,  and  Democratic  Administration,  New  York:  Association  Press,  1945. 
O£  particular  value  is  Rocthlisbergcr  and  Dickson,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  6.  See  also  Mayo, 
Elton  and  Others,  Teamwork^  and  Labor  Turnover  in  the  Aircraft  Industry  of  Southern  Cali- 
fornia, Boston:  Harvard  University  Press,  1944;  Rocthlisbergcr,  Fritz  J.,  Management  and 
Morale,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1941;  Gardner,  Burlcigh  B.,  Human  Relations 
in  Industry,  Chicago:  Irvin,  1945.  Relationships  between  informal  organization  and  super- 
vision are  suggested  by  Bradford,  L.  P.  and  Lippitt,  Ronald,  "Building  a  Democratic  Work 
Group,"  Personnel,  1945,  Vol.  22,  p.  142  ff.  The  implications  of  unionization  for  informal 
organization  arc  touched  upon  by  Bakke,  E.  Wight,  "Why  Workers  Join  Unions,*'  ibid.,  p. 
37  ff. 


312  INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION 

or  five  officials  at  the  bottom  of  action  papers  seem  to  have  a  magic  effect. 

Of  course,  the  "invincible  constellation"  may  conceivably  meet  defeat  at 
any  time.  However,  the  prestige  of  its  members  will  survive  occasional  de- 
feat if  the  decision  they  supported  continues  to  look  like  the  best  solution 
in  the  light  of  all  known  circumstances,  and  if  no  evidence  turns  up  to 
demonstrate  either  obvious  errors  of  judgment  or  inadequate  consideration 
of  all  the  factors  that  should  have  been  taken  into  account.  Their  craft 
demands  of  the  members  of  the  "invincible  constellation"  that  they  be 
masters  in  digesting  all  the  necessary  basic  information.  They  are  bound 
to  be  men  who  not  only  have  intimate  knowledge  of  the  department  and 
its  facilities  for  analysis  but  also  of  the  outside  interests  which  the  decision 
will  affect. 

Clubs  and  Clusters.  As  in  ordinary  ward  politics,  so  in  the  office  it  often 
pays  to  be  known  as  a  good  fellow,  and  to  be  active  in  good  fellowship. 
Assume  that  an  important  man  in  the  organization  loves  a  weekly  night  of 
poker  and  virile  conversation,  would  it  not  be  both  a  distinction  and  a 
privilege  to  be  asked  to  share  in  the  fun?  An  inexhaustible  supply  of  jokes 
may  buy  the  important  man's  jovial  interest  in  one's  career.  "An  entertain- 
ing chap,"  the  important  man  may  think;  "I  ought  to  see  more  of  him  in 
the  office."  And  during  poker  there  are  always  precious  opportunities  for 
posting  the  important  man  on  this  or  that.  Or  consider  the  Indiana  Club 
and  all  its  jolly  Hoosiers;  they  have  a  hard-working  program  committee, 
but  no  one  minds  a  discreet  business  conversation  in  the  corner.  Or  think 
of  the  wartime  car  pool,  and  how  gratifying  it  was  to  come  to  know  the 
section  chief  so  intimately.  The  car  pool  is  no  longer,  yet  its  off-the-record 
conversations  may  remain  a  regular  feature. 

Innocuous — and  desirable — as  these  groupings  are,  they  are  also  sources 
of  nonhierarchical  influence.  Illustrations  of  a  somewhat  different  charac- 
ter may  be  taken  from  the  annals  of  quite  a  few  of  the  quickly  recruited 
emergency  agencies,  especially  those  of  World  War  II.  Intensive  solidari- 
ties developed  among  occupational  groups — businessmen,  professors,  lawyers, 
civil  servants.  Each  group  tended  to  see  a  challenge  in  the  other.  Informal 
leadership,  if  only  for  purposes  of  vigilance,  found  ready  support  within 
the  individual  group.  In  fact,  spokesmen  discovered  it  to  be  to  their  ad- 
vantage not  to  be  caught  in  the  neutralizing  sphere  of  the  official  hierarchy, 
where  extremist  views  could  not  be  expressed  in  freedom.  Similar  forma- 
tions, based  on  general  outlook  rather  than  on  occupation,  are  by  no  means 
exceptional  in  old-line  establishments.  At  times  the  reformist  "Young 
Turks"  may  have  the  upper  hand,  reducing  those  who  are  other-minded  to 
the  role  of  the  "loyal  opposition" — loyal  or  not  so  loyal.  No  matter  how 
frequently  the  factional  position  will  be  reversed,  the  existence  of  a  "loyal 
opposition"  in  each  case  heightens  the  collective  sense  of  public  purpose  and 
helps  to  defeat  institutional  self-complacency. 

Nor  should  we  forget  the  "old  school  tie"  in  its  American  version,  which 


INFORMAL  ORGANIZATION  313 

is  considerably  less  obnoxious  than  the  British  prototype.  Still,  in  the  ad- 
ministrative staff  and  auxiliary  services  we  may  run  into  a  significant  scatter- 
ing of  Minnesota  men  or  Chicago  men  or  Syracuse  men.11  Quite  naturally, 
they  maintain  their  own  system  of  intercommunication,  develop  their  own 
sign  language,  and  generally  look  upon  one  another  with  fraternal  eyes. 
This  may  even  be  a  necessity  when  they  confront  the  most  honorable  federa- 
tion of  departmental  oldtimers. 

Voice  of  the  Union.  The  picture  would  hardly  be  complete  without 
some  indication  of  the  place  occupied  in  a  department  by  the  local  or  locals 
of  government-employee  unions.12  Unionization  has  received  new  impetus 
in  recent  years,  especially  among  the  rank  and  file.  It  should  be  admitted 
at  the  outset  that  collective  bargaining  in  the  public  service  must  take  dif- 
ferent forms  as  compared  with  industry,  particularly  because  compensation 
and  other  phases  of  the  work  relationship  are  ordinarily  the  subject  of  gov- 
ernment-wide and  even  statutory  regulation.  Nonetheless,  a  considerable 
field  remains  for  constructive  participation  of  chosen  employee  representa- 
tives in  various  aspects  of  the  managerial  process.  This  is  true  not  only  of 
grievance  procedure  and  the  promotion  of  employee  health,  welfare,  and 
safety  but  also  of  departmental  employee  relations  in  general. 

By  and  large,  the  working  contacts  of  employee  locals  have  been  con- 
fined to  the  personnel  office,  instead  of  fanning  out  over  the  organization. 
By  and  large,  too,  the  nature  of  these  contacts  has  held  the  local  too  much 
to  a  negative  role — raising  remonstrances  in  the  face  of  departmental  inten- 
tions or  actions.  That  this  need  not  be  the  case  has  been  demonstrated  by 
the  more  positive  approach  pursued  by  such  agencies  as  the  Tennessee 
Valley  Authority.  The  ultimate  administrative  producers  are  the  ordinary 
employees.  Work-simplification  programs  aimed  at  mass  processes,  for 
instance,  cannot  be  carried  along  by  first-line  supervisors  single-handedly. 
Programs  of  this  kind,  involving  a  higher  level  of  general  efficiency  and 
large  potential  economies,  must  enlist  every  employee.  It  will  not  always 
be  easy  to  win  the  rank  and  file,  but  without  first  settling  all  conceivable 
questions  with  their  legitimate  representatives  no  appeal  for  whole-hearted 
cooperation  is  likely  to  be  successful. 

The  leadership  of  an  agency  local  is  an  example  of  nonhierarchicai 
power  par  excellence.  It  may  be  a  nightmare  to  the  exponents  of  the  official 
hierarchy.  When  met  with  good  will  and  understanding,  however,  the 
union  can  be  a  source  of  real  support.  To  fight  a  running  battle  with  the 
local  entails  grave  risks  to  morale.  It  also  may  set  off  sparks  on  the  legisla- 
tive side,  and  embarrass  the  chief  executive  himself.  These  considerations 
invite  an  attitude  of  give-and-take,  even  though  negotiating  the  basic  terms 
of  such  give-and-take  may  be  tough  business. 

11  Cf.  above  Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  3,  "Training  for  Public 
Administration." 

12  Cf.  below  Ch.  24,  "Personnel  Standards,"  sec.  6,  "Employee  Relations." 


CHAPTER 


Interest  Groups  in  Administration 

1.  THE  MEANING  OF  INTEREST  REPRESENTATION 

Types  of  Interest  Groups.  Public  administration  operates  in  an  environ- 
ment of  interest-group  activity.  Most  of  the  agencies  of  government  are 
the  product  of  intergroup  pressure  or  conflict,  the  outcome  of  which  was 
establishment  of  a  governmental  body  to  perform  a  service  or  function  that 
had  been  carried  out  unsatisfactorily  or  not  at  all  under  conditions  of  private 
initiative.  Some  of  the  duties  of  the  oldest  federal  departments — Foreign 
Affairs,  Treasury,  War— included  the  protection,  promotion,  or  regulation, 
in  iMadison's  phrase,  of  "various  and  interfering  interests  .  .  .  [which] 
involves  the  spirit  of  party  and  faction  in  the  necessary  and  ordinary  opera- 
tions of  the  government."  Even  when  a  public  agency  secures  a  legislative 
mandate  to  perform  a  given  task  without  formal  relationship  to  the  group 
or  class  structure  of  society,  citizens  affected  by  that  task  watch  it  constantly^ 
and  make  their  views  known  through  some  collective  organization  or  agenu 

The  variety  and  scope  of  interest-group  activity  defy  efforts  toward 
simplification.  Students  of  interest-group  activity  have  concentrated  on 
describing  the  organization  and  activities  of  specific  organizations,  and  on 
making  case  studies  of  agencies  and  situations  in  which  group  pressures 
have  molded  or  modified  legislative  and  administrative  policy.1  The  latter 
method  succeeds  in  capturing  the  richness  and  vitality  of  governmental 
experience.  Yet  it  fails  to  yield  satisfactory  tools  of  interpretation  and  un- 
derstanding. We  need  more  descriptive  studies  and  reports,  but  we  also 
need  to  develop  concepts  and  methods  of  understanding  the  fundamental 

1  Cf.  Herring,  Pcndleton,  Group  Representation  Before  Congress,  Washington:  Brookings 
Institution,  1929,  and  Public  Administration  and  the  Public  Interest,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill, 
1936;  Childs,  H.  L.,  Labor  and  Capital  in  National  Politics,  New  York:  Harcourt  Brace,  1930; 
Crawford,  K.,  The  Pressure  Boys,  New  York:  Messncr,  1939;  Blaisdell,  D.  C.,  Economic 
Power  end  Political  Pressures,  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Monograph  No.  26, 
Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1941. 

314 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 


315 


motivation  and  distinctive  behavior  patterns  of  interest  groups.2  A  slightly 
revised  version  of  a  classification  suggested  by  Charles  A.  Beard  is  pre- 
sented below  to  give  some  idea  of  the  variety  of  interest  groups,  and  to 
emphasize  the  rise  of  professional  and  skill  groups  to  challenge  the  category 
of  economic  interests  that  until  recently  had  been  presumed  to  bt 
predominant. 

Major  Category  of  Interest  and  Basis  of 
Organization 

I.  ECONOMIC  ADVANTAGE 

A.   Industry^  commodity,  or  service 


B.   Federation  of  particular  interests 


Group  Organization 

A.  Trade    associations    and    indus- 
trial   institutes,  •  trade    unions, 
producer  cooperatives 

B.  Chamber  of  Commerce  of  the 
United  States,  National  Associa- 
tion of  Manufacturers,  Ameri- 
can  Farm    Bureau   Federation, 
National  Farmers  Union,  Amer- 
ican Federation  of  Labor,  Con- 
gress of  Industrial  Organizations 

C.  Consumers'  associations,  taxpay- 
ers' leagues 

A.  Bar   and    medical   associations, 
public   relations  counselors,   so- 
cial workers,  educators 

B.  Scientific  societies,  organizations 
of  public  officials 

National  Catholic  Welfare  Con- 
ference, Federal  Council  of 
Churches  of  Christ  in  America 

A.  Anti-Saloon   League,   Women's 
Christian  Temperance  Union 

B.  Relief    recipients,    veterans'    or- 
ganizations 

C.  Negro,  nationality  and  women's 
organizations 

Interest  Orientation  of  Public  Administration.  Pressure  groups  have  in 
common  a  self-regarding  singleness  of  aim  which  places  priority  of  impor- 
tance upon  the  immediate  purpose  or  welfare  of  the  group  organization  as 
such.  But  administrative  agencies  are  also  characterized  by  a  focus  of  aim 

2C/.  Bentley,  A.  F.,  The  Process  of  Government,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press, 
1908;  Perlman,  S.,  Theory  of  the  Labor  Movement,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1928;  Jordan,  E., 
The  Theory  of  Legislation,  Indianapolis:  Progress  Publishing  Co.,  1930;  Macmahon,  A.  W., 
'The  Mexican  Railways  under  Workers'  Administration,"  Public  Administration  Review. 
1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  458  ff.i  Chase,  S.,  Democracy  Under  Pressure.  New  York:  Twentieth  Century 
Fund,  1945. 


C.   Federation  of  general  interests 

II.  SKILL 

A.   Profession 


B.   Research  and  communication  of 

experience 
III.   RELIGION 


IV.   REFORM 

A.  Moral  causes 

B.  Improvement  of  group  status 

C.  Equalization  of  opportunity 


316  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

and  effort,  coupled  with  a  highly  developed  sense  of  organizational  im- 
portance. A  bureaucracy  transcends  the  particularism  of  pressure  groups 
only  by  the  oath  of  public  office  and  its  commitment  to  the  execution  of  a 
program  delegated  to  it  by  the  political  agencies  of  policy  formulation. 
Bureaucratic  theory  attempts  to  avoid  group  pressures  by  referring  them  to 
the  predetermined  legislative  policy  or  to  the  necessity  for  rules  and  regifr 
lations  applying  generally  to  all  groups  and  situations.  The  weakness  of 
this  formal  position  is  that  a  bureaucracy  is  itself  part  of  the  structure  of 
the  community,  and  the  achievement  of  its  specific  aim  is  in  large  measure 
dependent  upon  its  ability  to  secure  the  cooperation  and  support  of  other 
group  organizations.^ 

If  it  fails  to  do  so,  it  loses  a  valuable  opportunity  to  influence  the  course 
of  policy.  And  unless  it  does  so,  its  own  powers  and  organization  may  be 
modified  or  abolished  by  legislation  induced  by  pressure  from  dissatisfied 
groups  or  by  the  legislature's  own  dissatisfaction  with  the  inability  of  the 
bureaucracy  to  transform  the  relationships  between  conflicting  groups  from 
controversy  to  routine.  Administrative  agencies  must  keep  foremost  loyalty 
to  the  public  purpose  entrusted  to  them.  Still,  they  cannot  forget  that 
other  social  groups  share  in  that  purpose  and  have  their  own  notions  as 
to  how  it  may  best  be  achieved.  The  public  official  may  be  primarily  re- 
sponsible for  the  formulation  of  administrative  policy,  but  under  demo- 
cratic conditions  his  responsibility  does  not  make  him  the  sole  judge  of 
the  ends  of  policy.  The  wise  administrator,  therefore,  keeps  open  the 
channels  of  information  and  advice  between  his  agency  and  the  private 
organizations  concerned  with  its  operation)  Indeed,  the  only  question  is 
whether  these  channels  should  be  established  on  a  formal  basis  or  main- 
tained as  a  matter  of  informal  personal  contact. 

Governmentalization  of  Interest  Groups.  In  countries  where  the  scope 
of  governmental  responsibility  for  economic  enterprise  is  much  wider  than 
has  been  recognized  in  the  United  States,  this  interdependence  of  govern- 
mental and  economic  organization  becomes  an  integral  part  of  the  political 
structure.  The  Russian  trade  unions  and  cooperatives,  the  German  chambers 
of  industry,  and  the  Italian  corporations  became  in  effect  decentralized 
operating  divisions  of  the  central  policy-making  agency  controlling  the 
national  economy.8  In  that  role,  industrial  bodies  and  groups  participated 
in  the  formulation  of  policy  in  an  administrative  rather  than  a  political 
capacity,  losing  their  independence  and  their  opportunity  to  criticize  openly 
and  to  press  for  changes  in  the  direction  of  policy. 

8C/.  Webb,  Sidney  and  Beatrice,  Soviet  Communism:  A  New  Civilization?  New  York: 
Longmans,  1936;  Bicnstock,  Gregory  and  Others,  Management  in  Russian  Industry  and  Agri- 
culture, London:  Oxford  University  Press,  1944;  Sweezy,  Maxinc,  The  Structure  of  the  Nazi 
Economy,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1941;  International  Labor  Office,  Methods  of 
Collaboration  Between  Public  Authorities,  Workers'  and  Employers'  Organizations,  pt.  I, 
Geneva,  1940;  Brady,  Robert  A.,  Business  as  a  System  of  Power,  New  York:  Columbia  Uni- 
versity Press,  1943. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  317 

Interest  Groups  and  Class  Theory.  Returning  to  a  context  in  which  a 
distinction  is  maintained  between  private  initiative  and  governmental  con- 
trol in  economic  affairs,  we  may  observe  that  interest-group  activitity  in 
general  accepts  the  prevailing  structure  and  process  of  policy  formation. 
It  is  reformist  rather  than  revolutionary  in  orientation.  Interest  groups 
attempt  to  make  public  policy  the  instrument  of  their  aims.  Their  tech- 
niques include  the  methods  and  channels  of  publicity;  withholding  or 
offering  financial  or  voting  support;  sanctions  of  cooperation  or  non- 
cooperation;  and  personal  contacts  with  public  officials  through  innumerable 
channels  of  social,  professional,  and  official  association. 

(Jnterest-group  activity  is  in  a  category  of  thought  different  from  the 
Marxist  concept  of  class  interest,  which  presumes  an  irrepressible  conflict 
between  the  capitalists  and  the  workers.  This  ideology  looks  forward  to 
the  unification  of  political  and  economic  activity  in  the  name  of  an  authori- 
tative program  identified  with  the  interest  of  the  whole  people — or  the 
"classless  society.^  Less  inclusive  group  interests  are  labeled  as  collabora- 
tionist, diversionist,  or  reactionary.  Believers  in  the  class-interest  doctrine 
may  engage  in  pressure-group  tactics  pending  the  realization  of  the  classless 
society.  However,  they  do  so  without  a  sense  of  responsibility  for  the 
immediate  effects  of  policy,  for  their  deeper  moral  responsibility  is  for  the 
achievement  of  a  different  social  structure  and  a  new  political  order  of 
ideas,  rulers,  and  institutions. 

Demands  for  Interest  Representation.  'Historically,  the  class  interests  of 
property  were  reflected  for  hundreds  of  years  in  the  governmental  structure 
and  theory  of  representation  underlying  policy  formation.4  Since  the 
nineteenth  century,  however,  property  representation  as  such  has  almost 
completely  been  abolished  as  a  qualification  for  public  office.  A  partial 
recrudescence  of  class  representation  has  appeared  in  recent  years.  Certain 
group  interests,  particularly  labor  organizations,  have  raised  the  demand  for 
specific  representation  or  participation  in  the  formulation  of  public  policy. 
J  As  we  know,  there  are  always  either  formal  or  informal  relationships 
between  group  organizations  and  official  bureaucracies.  Furthermore,  it 
is  perfectly  cle^r  that  in  the  sense  of  the  right  to  be  heard,  to  be  consulted, 
and  to  be  informed  in  advance  of  the  tentative  basis  of  emerging  policy 
determination,  group  participation  is  a  fundamental  feature  of  democratic 
legislation  and  administration.  When,  therefore,  group  organizations  press 
for  representation  in  the  official  structure  of  administration,  their  desire 
reflects  some  deeper  motivation,  whether  it  be  redress  of  grievances,  <fe- 
sire  for  power,  resentment  over  too  limited  participation,  or  fears  of  insecurity. 

What  are  the  forms  and  types  of  interest  representation,  and  the  ways 
in  which  it  works?  In  the  following  sections  three  forms  will  be  analyzed, 
and  in  the  final  section  some  suggestions  will  be  presented  as  to  the  appro- 
priate conditions  and  basic  assumptions  of  such  interest  representation. 

*Cf.  Beard,  Charles  A.,  The  Economic  Basis  of  Politics.  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


318  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

2.  CLIENTELE  ORGANIZATION 

Growth  of  Clientele  Agencies.  Interest  representation  finds  expression 
indirectly  in  the  structure  of  government  when  an  agency  is  created  to 
benefit  a  special  category  of  citizens,  or  to  promote  the  welfare  of  a  group 
having  some  specified  interest  or  attribute  in  common.  The  best  known 
examples  are  perhaps  the  services  and  financial  aids  to  cxservicemen  by 
the  Veterans  Administration;  the  research,  promotional,  and  advisory  func- 
tions of  the  Women's  Bureau  in  furthering  equal  opportunities  and  non- 
discrimination  between  wage  earners  of  both  sexes;  the  comparable 
activities  and  grant-in-aid  responsibilities  of  the  Children's  Bureau  for  im- 
proving the  health,  education,  and  welfare  of  mothers  and  children;  the 
regulation  and  constructive  development  of  Indian  life  by  the  Office  of 
Indian  Affairs.  Clientele  organization  may  be  contrasted  with  the  more 
common  organization  by  function,  in  which  the  agency  is  established  to 
perform  a  function  or  service  for  all  categories  of  citizens,  such  as  a  public 
library  or  a  fire  department. 

A  function  may  be  so  defined  that,  in  effect,  it  is  restricted  to  a  major 
industrial  or  economic  group.  The  Federal  Reserve  System  operates  through 
reserve  banks  whose  operations  in  turn  are  restricted  to  banks.  The 
Securities  and  Exchange  Commission's  jurisdiction  is  restricted  to  security 
issuers,  traders,  and  organized  exchanges  engaged  in  security  transactions. 
The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  dealt  for  many  years  solely  with  the 
railroads  and  their  customers.  However,  when  the  administrative  function 
is  of  a  regulatory  rather  than  a  service  or  promotional  character,  the  im- 
plication is  that  two  or  more  adversary  interests  are  involved,  one  of  which 
— having  by  law  been  accorded  priority — is  represented  by  the  public  agency. 
In  such  cases,  the  clientele  principle  is  transvalued  by  clothing  the  group 
objective  wholly  or  in  part  with  the  public  interest.  This  objectification  of 
the  group  interest  in  public  policy  characterizes  a  great  deal  of  modern 
labor  and  agricultural  legislation. 

Disadvantages  of  Clientele  Organization.  From  the  standpoint  of 
economy  and  efficiency,  the  clientele  principle  is  defective  because  it  allows 
many  agencies  to  perform  essentially  the  same  basic  function  for  different 
classes  of  people.  In  practice,  of  course,  the  principle  is  not  carried  to  its 
logical  extreme.  Under  modern  conditions,  the  justification  for  clientele 
agencies  is  usually  based  on  special  circumstances,  coupled  with  a  welfare 
motive  that  assumes  the  desirability  of  governmental  ministration  to  the 
needs  of  an  unprotected  or  underprivileged  or  unrepresented  group.  The 
most  familiar  arguments  are  that  clientele  organizatioa  is  required  either 
to  redress  existing  inequalities  or  inequities  in  economic  and  social  life,  or 
to  handle  technical  problems  peculiar  to  an  economic  process  or  to  a  spe- 
cific class  of  citizens.  In  the  latter  case,  the  distinction  between  function 
and  clientele  loses  its  meaning,  because  every  functional  agency  has  to 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  319 

define  its  jurisdiction  to  include  certain  classes  of  people  or  cases  and  to  ex- 
clude others.  However,  although  clientele  agencies  may  be  formally  es- 
tablished to  perform  specified  functions,  this  does  not  make  them  functional 
in  purpose  or  scope. 

The  crux  of  the  problem  of  administrative  organization  turns  upon 
the  extent  to  which  the  agency  becomes  exclusive,  competitive,  or  self- 
centered  in  spirit.  An  agency  whose  activities  are  focused  and  directed 
toward  a  particular  group  is  likely  to  be  more  narrowly  centered  than  one 
established  to  perform  its  function  impartially  for  all  citizens.  Analysis  of 
governmental  structures  will  usually  reveal,  however,  some  functional  agen- 
cies which  have  a  focus  of  purpose  so  narrow  that  they  become  more  ex- 
clusive and  self-centered  than  a  clientele  agency  whose  interests  range  over 
a  broader  segment  of  the  population  or  national  economy.  Form  of 
organization,  whether  functional  or  clientele,  is  therefore  relative  to  the 
public  purpose  rather  than  to  the  particular  end  in  itself.  No  governmental 
agency  should  be  so  constituted  as  to  enable  a  single  group  to  prevent  the 
agency  from  taking  the  most  inclusive  view  of  the  public  interest  in  any 
given  situation.5 

Attempts  at  Internal  Balance  of  Interests.  One  way  of  implementing 
such  a  standard  would  be  to  create  agencies  with  so  broad  a  jurisdiction, 
covering  so  many  organized  groups,  that  the  interest  of  no  one  group  could 
be  controlling.  At  first  glance  this  idea  would  seem  to  have  been  followed 
in  the  creation  of  such  federal  departments  as  Agriculture,  Commerce,  and 
Labor.  The  functions  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture  include  research, 
information,  service,  and  regulation  of  processors,  distributors,  and  financiers 
as  well  as  a  great  variety  of  commodity  producers.  The  Department  of 
Commerce  deals  with  interests  represented  by  hundreds  of  industrial  prod- 
uct and  service  classifications  and  associational  groupings.  The  Department 
of  Labor's  statistical  and  regulatory  functions  affect  manufacturers  as  well 
as  scores  of  industrial  and  craft  unions.  All  this  splintering  of  "interests" 
fails,  however,  to  take  account  of  the  pressure  influences  behind  the  his- 
torical development  of  the  three  departments  and  of  the  psychological 
factor  that  the  great  federations  of  agricultural,  business,  and  labor  groups 
look  upon  each  department  as  their  spokesman  in  the  highest  councils  of 
the  executive  branch.6 

As  long  as  the  large  interest  groups  retain  any  degree  of  virility  and 
unity,  they  will  expect  great  weight  to  be  given  their  views  on  the  appoint- 
ment of  top  personnel  and  general  policy  matters.  No  government  can 
neglect  this  factor.  Indeed,  provided  the  operating  and  technical  levels  of 
administration  are  protected  from  political  interference  in  appointment  or 

6C/.  Brookings  Institution,  Investigation  of  Executive  Agencies,  ch.  2,  Senate  Doc.  No. 
1275,  75th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1937;  May,  Geoffrey,  "Day  Dreams  of  A  Bureau- 
crat," Public  Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  154. 

6  For  a  general  discussion,  see  Short,  L.  M.,  The  Development  of  National  Administrative 
Orfanization,  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1923. 


320  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

removal  of  personnel  and  in  the  handling  of  business,  it  seems  at  least 
arguable  whether  the  political  heads  of  these  departments  could  not  be  ap- 
pointed as  representatives  of  farmers,  businessmen,  or  wage  earners.  Aside 
from  a  broader  public  interest,  the  problem  at  this  level  raises  another 
issue,  namely,  the  need  of  the  chief  executive  for  a  department  head  and 
adviser  in  whom  he  has  complete  confidence,  while  a  group  representative 
by  definition  has  another  primary  loyalty.  The  dilemma  is  not  insurmount- 
able, but  it  requires  a  rare  combination  of  ability,  integrity,  and  flexibility 
to  serve  in  something  like  a  dual  capacity. 

Functions  of  Clientele  Agencies.  The  functions  most  often  delegated 
to  a  clientele  agency7  are  of  a  service  character:  research  and  exchange  of 
information.  The  systematic  reports  and  studies  of  the  agency  are  used  by 
the  clientele  group  or  by  other  groups  to  press  for  desired  legislation  or 
changes  in  administrative  policy.  Another  function  is  the  formulation  of 
standards,  whether  of  equity  and  health — as  in  the  employment  of  women 
and  children — or  for  the  protection  of  criteria  of  competence  and  training 
to  be  applied  by  state  professional  and  trade  examining  boards.  In  the 
latter  case,  the  standards  are  authoritative  rather  than  advisory.  They 
raise  the  question  of  formal  delegation  of  rule-making  power  to  private 
groups,  since  such  boards  are  usually  composed  of  representatives  of  the 
professional  or  trade  groups  that  are  seeking  state  regulation  of  admission 
to  the  profession  or  trade.8  Inevitably,  the  standards  established  have  an 
economic  effect  in  limiting  the  number  of  those  admitted  to  the  profession 
or  trade.  However,  delegation  of  this  power  to  private  associations  has 
been  justified  by  courts  and  legislatures  because  technical  and  specialized 
training  cannot  be  maintained  without  rigorous  tests  of  proficiency. 

Generally  speaking,  the  endowment  of  clientele  agencies  with  regulatory 
responsibilities  runs  counter  to  deeply  felt  ideas  of  equity  and  fairness.  The 
assumption  prevails  that  an  agency  responsible  for  promoting  the  welfare 
of  a  particular  group  or  class  of  citizens  cannot  be  expected  to  maintain 
judicial  attitudes  of  impartiality  in  a  dispute  involving  an  interest  adversary 
to  that  which  the  agency  is  supposed  to  protect  or  promote.  This  is  one  of 
the  outstanding  reasons  for  the  creation  of  independent  regulatory  commis- 
sions outside  the  structure  of  the  executive  departments.  The  objection 
can  be  disposed  of  technically  by  protecting  the  regulatory  tribunal,  wher- 
ever it  be  located,  from  political  or  other  interference  in  the  handling  of 
its  cases.  The  Department  of  Agriculture,  for  instance,  has  many  regula- 
tory duties  which  are  administered  by  single-headed  bureaus  fairly  and 

7  The  Office  of  Indian  Affairs  in  the  Department  of  the  Interior  presents  a  special  case 
because  it  performs  practically  all  governmental  functions  in  the  areas  placed  under  its  juris- 
diction.   Cf.   Meriam,   Lewis,   The  Administration  of  Indian  Affairs,  Washington:   Brookings 
Institution,  1928. 

8  The  legal  questions  are  discussed  by  Jaffe,  L.  L.,  "Law  Making  by  Private  Groups," 
Harvard  Law  Review,  1937,  Vol.  51,  p.  201  ff.    See  generally  Carr  Saunders,  A.  M.  and 
Wilson,  P.  A.,  The  Professions,  London:  Oxford  University  Press,  1933. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  321 

equitably  enough  to  pass  the  test  of  judicial  scrutiny  by  the  Supreme  Court.9 
Organizational  independence  has  retained  its  strength  as  a  symbol  of 
fairness  in  most  areas  of  federal  regulatory  administration. 

Experiences  of  the  Great  Depression  and  World  War  II.  Emergency 
legislation  to  meet  conditions  of  economic  depression,  such  as  the  National 
Industrial  Recovery  Act  of  1933  and  the  mobilization  of  industry  and  agri- 
culture in  World  War  II,  resulted  in  a  mushroom  growth  of  clientele 
agencies.  The  hundreds  of  NRA  code  authorities,  hailed  at  the  beginning 
of  the  New  Deal  as  experiments  in  industrial  self-government,  were  later 
vilified  as  promoting  monopolies  and  enabling  minority  groups  to  legislate 
for  their  private  ends.10  But  the  mood  was  passing.  Faced  with  the  exi- 
gencies of  defense  and  war  production  programs,  the  Office  of  Production 
Management — and  subsequently  the  War  Production  Board,  the  Office  of 
Price  Administration,  the  War  Food  Administration,  the  Office  of  Defense 
Transportation  and  the  Petroleum  Administration  for  War — all  developed 
an  organization  based  upon  industrial  processes  or  commodity  groupings, 
and  in  many  cases  staffed  by  men  drawn  from  the  ranks  of  the  industries 
concerned. 

With  the  exception  of  the  ODT  and  PAW,  the  main  pattern  of  organi- 
zation was  one  of  function  and  process — for  example,  production  and 
materials  controls,  price  and  rationing  controls,  food  production  and  dis- 
tribution. However,  the  industry  and  commodity  divisions  played  a  prom- 
inent role  in  formulating  limitation  and  allocation  orders  or  price  and 
marketing  regulations,  in  handling  priority  applications,  and  in  collecting 
and  analyzing  statistical  information.  In  the  fields  of  petroleum  production 
and  distribution  and  of  railroad  transportation,  the  agencies  were  frankly 
constituted  and  staffed  on  an  industry  basis.  Although  headed  in  each 
instance  by  a  public  official  responsible  to  the  President,  they  relied  pri- 
marily upon  industry  initiative  and  cooperation  in  developing  and  carrying 
out  the  changes  in  business  practices  necessary  to  meet  wartime  require- 
ments. 

In  short,  it  was  recognized  that  our  normal  governmental  machinery 
and  personnel  had  to  be  supplemented  to  meet  the  demands  of  war;  that 
over-all  policies  and  controls  should  not  be  delegated  in  toto  to  the  broadest 
industrial  groupings;  and  that  a  basis  of  organization  had  to  be  evolved 
that  would  conduce  to  maintaining  contacts  with  the  regulated  groups, 
securing  their  advice  and  active  cooperation,  giving  them  prominence  in 
announcing  and  promulgating  administrative  policies  and  regulations,  and 
enlisting  them  for  much  of  the  routine  work  of  administration.  The  con- 
flicts of  policy  between  the  agencies  built  on  industry  or  clientele  and  the 
9C/.  Kitchen,  C.  W.,  "Regulatory  Procedures  in  Agricultural  Marketing  and  Food  Dis- 
tribution," in  the  symposium  entitled  Lectures  on  Administrative  Regulation,  Washington: 
Department  of  Agriculture  Graduate  School,  1945. 

10  C/.   Lyon,   L.   S.   and   Others,   The  National  Recovery  Administration,  Washington: 
Brookings  Institution,  1935. 


322  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

functional  agencies  of  control  above  them,  like  the  Office  of  War  Mobili- 
zation, yield  some  classic  case  studies  in  administration.  It  is  probable, 
however,  that  these  conflicts  reflected  bottlenecks  or  divergencies  in  pro- 
duction programs  that  would  have  plagued  the  war  effort  in  any  event 
regardless  of  organizational  forms. 

Two  general  observations  stand  out.  First,  any  agency  which  seeks 
special  treatment,  privilege,  or  protection  for  particular  groups  deprives 
itself  of  a  justifiable  claim  to  the  administrative  responsibility  for  executing 
more  inclusive  general  policies  of  government.  Second,  while  in  special 
cases  a  group  purpose  may  be  identified  with  the  general  welfare  and  with 
statutory  policy,  the  primary  concern  of  any  organized  group  is  with  the 
naming  of  administrative  top  personnel  and  the  content  of  policy, 

3.  STAFFING  FOR  POINT  OF  VIEW 

Grounds  for  Interest  Representation.  The  question  may  be  asked 
whether  it  is  possible  to  distinguish  between  the  content  or  substance  of  ad- 
ministrative policies  and  the  officers  who  are  responsible  for  policy  making. 
In  the  process  of  policy  formulation,  the  substance  of  decisions  reached 
is  extremely  difficult  to  dissociate  from  the  personalities  and  social  attitudes 
of  those  participating.  The  "organization  product"  is  rarely  an  individual 
idea.  It  is  usually  the  fruit  of  a  great  deal  of  preliminary  discussion  and 
informal  memoranda.  Ultimately  it  turns  out  in  the  form  of  a  letter,  state- 
ment, message,  or  order  which  has  been  reviewed  and  initialed  by  repre- 
sentatives of  many  different  parts  of  the  organization.11  Realizing  the 
relatively  indeterminate  character  of  administrative  policy-making  and  the 
importance  of  participation  in  the  developmental  stages,  some  interest  groups 
— particularly  labor  organizations— have  requested  representation  in  admin- 
istration on  three  grounds:  first,  that  such  group  representation  is  desirable 
to  equalize  opportunities  for  protecting  and  safeguarding  respective  inter- 
ests; second,  that  organized  groups  can  make  contributions  of  special 
knowledge  and  experience  which  would  not  otherwise  be  available  to  public 
agencies;  and  third,  that  group  participation  in  policy  formulation  makes 
possible  the  avoidance  of  mistakes  and  the  integration  of  diverse  viewpoints 
in  advance  of  formal  action  on  policy  proposals. 

Before  discussing  the  different  forms  that  group  representation  may  take, 
we  should  say  that  there  is  a  practical  difference  between  demands  for 
representation  that  arise  from  distrust  of  the  administrative  top  personnel 
and  demands  for  changes  in  agency  rules  or  policies.  Administrators  may 
isolate  themselves  from  leaders  and  currents  of  group  opinion.  But  by 
doing  so,  they  lose  a  valuable  opportunity  for  developing  mutual  respect 
and  confidence  that  may  be  gained  through  continued  formal  or  informal 
contacts  with  outside  interests.  Self-isolation  interferes  with  the  all-im- 

11  Cf.  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  ch.  8:  "Wanted:  An  Organization  Product,'*  New 
York:  Knopf,  1945. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  323 

portant  impression  of  fairness — the  public  conviction  that  decisions  are 
made  only  after  full  investigation  and  consideration  of  the  facts,  which  in- 
cludes taking  into  account  the  positions  and  viewpoints  of  group  spokesmen. 
Such  institutionalized  contacts  and  the  application  of  elementary  principles 
of  judicious  procedure  can  go  far  to  protect  administrators  from  charges 
of  bias,  unfamiliarity  with  their  job,  inside  manipulation,  and  "politics" 
in  making  decisons. 

Demands  for  group  representation  that  are  motivated  by  a  desire  to  in- 
fluence policy  can  be  met  in  a  variety  of  ways.  Members  of  regulatory 
boards  and  commissions  are  usually  prohibited  from  having  any  financial 
interest  in  concerns  to  be  regulated  and  from  engaging  in  any  other  voca- 
tion, trade,  or  employment.  In  such  agencies,  the  demands  and  views  of 
affected  groups  are  expected  to  be  considered  through  legal  procedures  of 
investigation  and  notice  and  through  opportunity  for  hearing  prior  to  a 
formal  decision,  regulation,  or  order.  A  more  direct  device — which  will  be 
considered  in  the  next  section — is  the  appointment  of  a  representative  ad- 
ministrative board  whose  members  are  nominated  by  interest  groups.  A 
third  technique  is  the  appointment  of  administrative  personnel  on  grounds 
of  special  vocational  experience  or  affiliation.  One  form  of  this  device  is  the 
creation  of  a  special  staff  unit  to  maintain  contacts  with  outside  groups  and 
to  present  their  grievances,  claims,  or  suggestions  to  the  appropriate  officials. 

Administrative  Appointment  of  Interest  Representatives.  The  appoint- 
ment of  individuals  to  public  office  because  of  group  affiliation  squarely 
conflicts  with  the  civil  service  concept  of  appointment  by  virtue  of  merit 
established  by  competitive  examination.  Fortunately,  the  two  principles 
are  not  incompatible.  Group  affiliation  or  vocational  experience  may  go 
hand  in  hand  with  merit  and  qualification.  The  question  of  propriety  in 
appointing  group  representatives  who  retain  connections  of  personal  loyalty 
or  financial  interest  in  private  organizations  rests  upon  other  grounds. 

During  World  War  II,  one  type  of  such  representation  was  the  practice 
of  appointing  $l-a-year  men  by  agencies  like  the  War  Production  Board. 
The  Office  of  Defense  Transportation  in  certain  cases  employed  its  top 
personnel  on  a  "without  compensation"  basis,  the  private  employer— a  rail- 
road— paying  the  executives  their  regular  salaries.  The  Petroleum  Admin- 
istration for  War  adopted  the  practice  of  paying  regular  government  salaries, 
but  many  of  its  executives  received  the  difference  between  their  public  pay 
and  their  private  salaries  from  their  previous  employer.  Representatives  of 
labor  organizations  appointed  to  top  administrative  posts  usually  fol- 
lowed the  principle  of  accepting  government  positions  but  served  only  part 
time.  They  and  their  labor  alternates  received  compensation  on  a  when- 
actually-employed  basis.  At  lower  levels,  public  employees  appointed  as 


324  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

labor  representatives  accepted  government  salaries  and  devoted  full  time 
to  their  responsibilities.12 

The  practice  of  dual  compensation,  or  recognition  of  dual  allegiance  to 
public  and  private  organizations,  arose  in  part  from  the  lack  of  men  and 
women  in  government  service  trained  in  industry  operations,  familiar  with 
the  influential  industry  leaders,  and  capable  of  swiftly  grasping  the  peculiar 
wartime  problems  in  developing  programs  of  economic  mobilization  and 
control.  With  such  outstanding  exceptions  as  Ickes,  Eastman,  and  Hender- 
son, the  slower-moving  governmental  processes  of  professional  research  and 
regulation  were  for  the  most  part  by-passed  for  the  presumed  advantages  of 
business  experience  in  initiating  and  administering  the  war  programs.  The 
policy  of  appointing  outsiders  who  retained  their  financial  or  business  con- 
nections had  definite  drawbacks.  It  gave  countenance  to  charges  by  other 
businessmen  of  special  privilege  and  big-business  domination,  and  lent 
support  to  demands  for  representation  of  other  groups. 

Problems  of  Dual  Allegiance.  Julius  A.  Krug,  then  director  of  the 
War  Production  Board's  Office  of  War  Utilities,  and  Ralph  Davies,  deputy 
of  the  Petroleum  Administrator  for  War,  attempted  to  meet  these  charges 
by  a  so-called  "melting-pot"  policy.  It  consisted  of  recruiting  men  from 
all  branches  and  interests  in  the  electric  power  and  petroleum  industries — 
publicly  and  privately  owned  enterprises,  integrated  and  independent  com- 
panies, state  regulatory  commissions,  and  so  on.  The  first  two  adminis- 
trators of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  who  maintained  a  policy  of 
personal  disinterestedness  of  top  price  executives,  were  pilloried  before 
Congress  and  the  public  for  relying  in  too  great  measure  upon  economics 
professors  in  administering  price  control  and  rationing.  The  melting-pot 
policy,  if  it  did  not  eliminate  charges  of  special-interest  domination,  was 
rationalized  by  the  respective  administrators  on  the  ground  that  it  gave  them 
the  benefit  of  variety  of  training,  experience,  and  ability  in  policy  formu- 
lation and  execution. 

12  Apparently  there  is  no  legal  barrier  to  the  receipt  of  private  payment  for  services  ren- 
dered exclusively  to  private  persons  or  organizations  when  such  services  have  no  connection 
with  the  services  rendered  to  the  government.  Civil  Service  Act,  Rules,  and  Regulations  (an- 
notated), p.  442.  A  federal  statute  of  1917  provided  that  after  July  1,  1919,  "no  government 
official  or  employee  shall  receive  any  salary  in  connection  with  his  services  as  such  an  official 
or  employee  from  any  source  other  than  the  government  of  the  United  States,  except  as  may 
be  contributed  out  of  the  Treasury  of  any  State,  county  or  municipality,  and  no  person,  asso- 
ciation or  corporation  shall  make  any  contribution  to,  or  in  any  way  supplement  the  salary 
of,  any  government  official  or  employee  for  the  services  performed  by  him  for  the  government 
of  the  United  Statacs"  (violations  are  misdemeanors  punishable  by  fine  of  not  less  than 
$1,000  or  imprisonment  for  not  less  than  six  months,  or  both);  5  U.  S.  C.  66.  This  provision 
applies  to  salaries  received  from  a  private  person  or  source  as  compensation  or  part  compen- 
sation for  the  services  rendered  to  the  government,  and  to  compensation  received  if  the 
officer  or  employee  renders  the  same  or  similar  services  to  both  the  government  and  a  private 
person.  33  Op.  Atty.  Gen.  273  (1922);  38  Op.  Atty.  Gen.  294  (1935);  39  pp.  Atty.  Gen. 
501  (1940).  See  also  Kirchheimcr,  Otto,  "The  Historical  and  Comparative  Background  of  the 
Hatch  Law,"  in  Friedrich,  Carl  J.  and  Mason,  Edward  S.,  eds.,  Public  Policy,  Vol.  2,  p.  341  ff., 
Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1941. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  325 

The  concept  of  coordination  as  maintaining  a  variety  and  balance  of 
diverse  personalities  and  viewpoints  within  organizations  is  a  familiar  one 
in  administrative  theory.13  Conceived  in  terms  of  competition  in  ideas  and 
incentive  for  keeping  the  top  administrator  informed  as  to  what  is  going 
on  in  his  organization,  such  a  policy  encourages  vigor  and  initiative  all 
down  the  line.  The  condition  of  its  effectiveness  in  a  cooperative  system  is, 
however,  that  the  participants  accept  as  preeminent  the  common  purpose 
of  the  organization,  and  that  the  divergences  in  understanding  and  inter- 
pretation of  that  purpose  do  not  undermine  belief  in  its  reality  as  the  or- 
ganization objective.  While  functional  specialization  is  certainly  compatible 
with  organizational  unity,  it  is  also  well  recognized  that  the  widest  dis- 
parity of  individual  motives  may  still  contribute  to  cooperative  effort.  A 
general  statement  of  objectives  permits  wide  differences  in  interpretation 
as  to  the  best  means  for  accomplishing  the  organizational  purpose.  However, 
neither  particular  individuals  nor  units  of  the  staff  should  be  given  reason 
to  conclude  that  other  individuals  or  staff  sectors  holding  conflicting  views 
on  policy  have  a  truer  grasp  of  the  general  purpose  or  an  inside  track  in 
policy  councils.  Systematic  encouragement  of  conflicting  views  tends  to 
undermine  the  necessary  will-to-cooperate  on  the  lower  levels  of  organiza- 
tional life.  It  comes  dangerously  close  to  creating  internal  ideological  con- 
troversies which  few  administrators  can  afford  to  tolerate. 

A  sound  recruitment  policy  in  any  line  organization  consciously  aim! 
at  securing  a  representative  distribution  or  cross  section  of  social  experience 
in  its  staff.  Such  differences,  so  far  as  possible,  should  be  kept  on  an  indi- 
Ividual  basis,  with  a  view  to  appealing  to  individual  incentives  and  desire 
for  rewards  which  will  contribute  toward  attainment  of  the  general  goal. 
Introduction  of  conflicting  goals  imperils  the  realization  of  the  highest 
value  within  the  organization.  From  the  standpoint  of  an  individual  who 
thinks  of  himself  as  representing  an  outside  group  and  conscientiously  strives 
to  maintain  two  loyalties,  the  experience  is  apt  to  be  an  extremely  frustrating 
and  unhappy  one,  unless  he  happens  to  be  an  aggressive  personality  who 
finds  self-expression  in  conflict  regardless  of  outcome. 

Acceptance  of  a  job  without  acceptance  of  the  authoritatively  expressed 
major  purpose  of  the  undertaking  is  a  self-defeating  act  unless  the  individual 
adopts  a  pressure-group  attitude  which  detracts  from  his  usefulness  at 
operating  levels.  The  outside  group  which  favors  "representation"  but 
claims  that  agreement  can  be  reached  on  methods  of  administration  will 
soon  be  faced  with  two  lessons  of  experience:  First,  the  outside  group  is 
bound  to  lose  confidence  in  its  representative  when  he  is  identified  with  the 
bureaucracy  as  a  jobholder;  second,  the  public  employee  who  thinks  of 

13  Cf.  Dennison,  Henry  S.,  Organization  Engineering,  New  York:  Button,  1931;  Barnard, 
Chester  I.,  The  Functions  of  the  Executive,  pp.  86-94,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press, 
1938;  Follett,  Mary  P.,  Dynamic  Administration,  pp.  96-116,  New  York:  Harper,  1941. 


326  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

himself  as  a  group  representative  will  have  the  greatest  difficulty  in  accept- 
ing the  channels  and  levels  of  authority  required  by  the  organization. 

Group  Representation  Through  Special  Staff  Units.  Some  agencies  have 
deliberately  incorporated  the  formal  principle  of  interest  representation  by 
creating  staff  units  on  policy,  linked  to  outside  groups  and  maintaining 
liaison  relationships  with  operating  divisions.  Examples  are  the  labor,  busi- 
ness, and  consumer  advisory  boards  of  the  National  Recovery  Administra- 
tion, and  the  Offices  of  Labor  Production,  Manpower  Requirements  and 
Civilian  Requirements  in  the  War  Production  Board.  The  NRA  advisory 
boards  were  given  a  formal  power  of  withholding  their  assent  to  a  code 
of  fair  competition  to  be  approved  by  the  NRA  administrator,  later  the 
National  Industrial  Recovery  Board.  The  labor  and  consumer  boards 
naturally  used  this  power  to  delay  the  promulgation  of  codes  until  the 
labor  and  price  provisions  were  satisfactory  to  them. 

The  process  of  negotiating  codes  took  on  bargaining  aspects  which  had 
both  good  and  bad  results.  The  boards  established  some  standards  of  phrase- 
ology and  policy  which  were  accepted  by  the  administrator  and  his  deputies. 
These  standards  improved  the  administrative  feasibility  of  the  codes  and 
helped  to  raise  the  level  of  competitive  practices  in  industry.  At  the  same 
time,  the  boards  and  their  staffs  psychologically  separated  themselves  from 
the  code  administrators  and  developed  a  corporate  unity  and  loyalty  of 
their  own.  This  resulted  in  a  lack  of  consensus  on  the  purpose  of  NRA  and 
an  attitude  of  irresponsibility  toward  the  administrator's  problems.  The  veto 
power  had  to  be  used  too  often  and  came  to  be  overridden  by  the  adminis- 
trator as  a  matter  of  form,  accentuating  the  lack  of  sympathy  and  mutual 
deference. 

At  the  top  level  the  boards  met  separately  and  moved  progressively  away 
from  close  touch  with  the  administrator,  while  their  staff  members  were 
inhibited  from  assuming  the  role  of  technical  advisers  to  the  code  adminis- 
trators. It  was  only  for  a  brief  period  of  six  months  prior  to  the  judicial 
burial  of  NRA  that  a  smooth-working  device  of  policy  coordination  was 
developed  from  the  boards.  This  was  an  advisory  council  composed  of  two 
top  staff  members  from  each  board,  created  to  review  policy  questions  aris- 
ing under  any  code  of  fair  competition.  The  council  acted  as  a  group  of 
technical  experts,  who  secured  full  reports  and  investigations  from  their 
own  staffs  as  well  as  the  code  administrators.  It  thus  carved  out  a  role  of 
authoritative  advice  to  the  National  Industrial  Recovery  Board.  It  is  note- 
worthy that  the  council  developed  into  an  effective  tool  in  supervising  the 
actual  administration  of  the  codes  after  they  had  been  negotiated  and 
promulgated.  It  therefore  conflicted  squarely  with  the  principle  of  industrial 
self-government  by  code  authorities  in  the  initiation  of  changes  in  general 
NRA  policy. 

When  the  Office  of  Production  Management  was  created  soon  after  the 
inception  of  the  defense  program,  a  novel  form  of  interest  representation 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  327 

was  adopted.  Administrative  authority  was  divided  between  Director  Gen- 
eral William  S.  Knudsen  and  Associate  Director  General  Sidney  Hillman. 
The  latter  was  responsible  for  a  Labor  Division,  headed  by  a  Princeton 
economist,  J.  Douglas  Brown.  The  Labor  Division  was  plagued  by  the 
distrust  of  trade  union  leaders  toward  the  "technicians"  on  Brown's  staff 
when  the  chips  were  down  on  issues  of  industrial  reconversion  for  war. 
There  was  no  such  thing  as  preparing  for  war  by  writing  codes  of  regula- 
tion. With  little  time  to  bargain  about  methods,  the  question  was  how  to 
get  out  war  production.  The  story  of  labor  representation  in  the  period 
of  reconversion  to  war  remains  to  be  written,  but  its  main  elements  are 
likely  to  be:  (1)  industrial  and  military  insistence  upon  the  policy  initiative; 
(2)  distrust  of  labor  participation  on  issues  of  military  or  management  prerog- 
ative; (3)  labor's  attempt  to  influence  policy  by  securing  separate  representa- 
tion and  by  making  demands  in  policy  conferences  on  a  bargaining  basis; 
and  (4)  labor's  refusal  to  permit  bureaucrats,  even  those  selected  by  its 
own  leaders,  to  make  by  themselves  final  commitments  or  binding  decisions 
as  a  matter  of  administrative  policy. 

After  Hillman's  undermined  health  had  forced  him  to  leave  his  post 
and  a  more  unitary  top  control  over  war  production  had  been  installed 
under  Donald  Nelson,  the  Labor  Division  was  replaced  at  presidential  direc- 
tion by  an  Office  of  Labor  Production,  reporting  to  the  chairman  of  the 
War  Production  Board.  The  first  director  of  the  new  agency,  a  former 
Michigan  Commissioner  of  Labor,  was  replaced  early  in  1943  by  Joseph  B. 
Keenan  of  the  American  Federation  of  Labor.  At  the  same  time,  a  new 
Office  of  Manpower  Requirements  was  created  under  Clinton  S.  Golden 
of  the  Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations.  The  representative  character  of 
these  men  could  not  be  questioned  by  the  unions.  As  the  pattern  of  WPB 
limitation  and  allocation  orders,  priority  administration,  and  budgeting  of 
controlled  materials  had  by  this  time  been  established,  Keenan  and  Golden 
turned  their  attention  to  the  problems  of  developing  channels  of  communi- 
cation, information,  and  influence  within  the  complex  WPB  organization. 

In  this  effort,  they  relied  largely  upon  their  deputies,  George  Brooks  and 
Ralph  Hetzel,  who  were  experienced  in  the  intricacies  of  administration  and 
appreciated  the  necessity  of  conforming  to  the  conditions  of  bureaucratic 
cooperation.  With  few  exceptions,  they  succeeded  in  settling  their  internal 
problems,  and  worked  out  procedures  for  placing  a  labor  representative  in 
each  industry  division  or  bureau  to  advise  on  labor  matters  arising  under 
the  WPB  programs.  Their  major  problem  became  in  fact  that  of  staking 
claim  to  functions  which  other  labor  agencies— the  Department  of  Labor 
in  labor  disputes  and  the  War  Manpower  Commission  in  securing  adequate 
sources  of  labor  supply — would  recognize  as  falling  within  the  province 
of  WPB. 

As  long  as  the  chairman  of  WPB  considered  the  participation  of  labor 
valuable  in  the  stimulation  of  production  and  the  administration  of  mate- 


328  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

rials  allocation  or  limitation  orders,  labor's  advisory  position  within  WPB 
was  protected.  Toward  the  end  in  the  area  production-committee  approach 
and  in  the  termination  of  war  contracts,  the  labor  units  shifted  their  pro- 
grams from  an  emphasis  on  influencing  top  policy  to  one  on  cooperating 
with  other  units  in  the  organization  in  coordinating  administrative  policy, 
on  the  whole  with  somewhat  less  effectiveness  than  had  the  staff  of  the  labor 
advisory  board  in  the  NRA  advisory  council.  Again,  as  in  NRA,  it  was  in  the 
declining  rather  than  the  formative  period  that  labor  representation  through 
special  staff  units  really  tackled  the  problems  of  organizing  for  effectual 
work  in  a  complex  hierarchical  organization.  Only  then  was  definite  prog- 
ress made  toward  gaining  matter-of-course  recognition  by  officials  at  all 
policy  levels  in  the  agency  for  the  labor  staff  members'  contribution  in  in- 
formation, ideas,  and  ingenuity. 

We  may  question,  however,  whether  labor  organizations  generally  have 
grasped  the  significance  of  this  lesson.  Or,  if  they  have,  whether  they  look 
upon  their  experience  as  a  failure  in  labor  representation,  with  the  inference 
that  they  should  press  for  more  influential  jobs  next  time  rather  than  search 
for  an  effective  device  to  influence  policy  from  the  labor  point  of  view. 

Consumer  representation  in  the  war  effort  was  divided  at  a  very  early 
stage.  In  1941,  the  Office  of  Price  Administration  and  Civilian  Supply  was 
reduced  in  jurisdiction  and  title  to  OP  A.  The  function  of  securing  an  ade- 
quate production  of  materials  and  goods  for  nonmilitary  uses  was  placed 
in  the  Office  of  Production  Management,  where  the  consumer  interest  was 
very  largely  considered  in  terms  of  the  problems  of  the  manufacturers  of 
civilian-type  goods  and  materials.  Originally  staffed  mainly  by  economists 
under  Leon  Henderson,  the  OPM  Office  of  Civilian  Supply  eventually  be- 
came the  Office  of  Civilian  Requirements.  It  was  gradually  transformed 
into  a  group  of  broadminded  businessmen  with  the  functions  of  advising 
the  industry  divisions  on  production  and  materials  problems  from  an  over- 
all standpoint,  and  of  acting  as  a  claimant  agency  for  the  controlled  mate- 
rials left  over  after  the  military  and  strategic  civilian  claimants  had  justified 
their  requirements  to  the  program  vice-chairman  and  the  requirements  com- 
mittee of  WPB.  During  a  limited  period  in  1942,  the  office  did  in  effect 
make  strategic  determinations  as  to  materials  allocation.  However,  this  was 
terminated  when  the  program  vice-chairman  became  responsible  for  allo- 
cating materials  among  competing  military  and  civilian  uses. 

The  general  consumer  interest  was  therefore  split  up,  in  terms  of  the 
functional  division  of  labor,  between  production  control  in  WPB  and  price 
control  in  OPA.  The  latter  inevitably  pushed  for  precedence  over  produc- 
tion urgencies  and  was  usually  in  opposition  to  WPB  requests  for  higher 
prices  to  elicit  increases  in  production.  The  domestic  consumer  interest 
became  identified  with  a  total  agency  function.  At  no  time  was  specific 
representation  demanded  by  consumers  as  a  group.  Industrial  consumers 
or  producers,  however,  secured  a  congressional  proviso  on  OPA's  funds 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  329 

requiring  that  no  official  receiving  more  than  $4,500  a  year  should  have  had 
less  than  five  years'  responsible  "business"  experience.  Here  again,  Leon 
Henderson's  professional  economist-administrators  were  gradually  replaced 
by  men  of  business  training  and  background.  Whether  the  later  appointees 
were  better  administrators  than  their  predecessors  remains  to  be  proved. 
In  any  event,  the  supporters  of  price  control  did  not  renounce  their  faith  in 
OPA  because  of  this  development,  nor  did  the  record  of  price  control  there- 
after show  any  trend  unfavorable  to  price  stabilization  until  several  months 
after  V-J  Day. 

Balance  Sheet  of  Experience.  Objectively,  the  policy  of  staffing  adminis- 
trative agencies  for  "point  of  view"  involves  two  logically  contradictory  cri- 
teria of  selection  and  training.  The  responsibility  of  the  administrator  for 
achieving  results  under  the  policy  of  the  law  called  for  authority  to  appoint 
subordinates  upon  whose  ability  and  judgment  he  could  rely.  At  the  same 
time,  responsibility  and  loyalty  of  his  administrative  subordinates  were  to 
symbols  or  organizations  outside  the  agency  by  which  they  were  employed. 

It  may  readily  be  admitted  that  administrative  ingenuity  should  not  be 
stultified  by  logical  dilemmas.  In  the  first  place,  when  the  factors  of  time 
and  place  are  taken  into  account,  it  is  conceivable  that  nine-tenths  of  the 
employee's  job  will  never  raise  a  conflict  between  his  two  loyalties.  Sec- 
ondly, the  administrator  may  find  ways  of  canalizing  or  utilizing  the 
energies  of  interest  representatives  so  as  not  to  interfere  with  vital  parts 
of  his  program.  Thirdly,  in  many  cases,  the  interests  of  outside  groups  may 
be  complementary  to  his  own,  and  mutual  exploration  of  policy  alternatives 
may  remove  barriers  raised  by  institutional  distance,  misunderstanding,  and 
errors  in  judgment.  Considerations  such  as  these,  however,  can  be  met  by 
arrangements  which  do  not  impose  equal  strains  on  lines  of  administrative 
responsibility  and  individual  personalities. 

The  legitimate  aspirations  of  labor,  consumer,  or  citizen  groups  for  more 
effective  participation  in  administrative  policy-making  should  not  be  di- 
rected toward  securing  positions  as  group  representatives  at  operating  or 
technical  levels.  Creation  of  representative  staff  units  at  the  top-policy  level, 
reporting  directly  to  the  administrator,  may  have  some  public-relations  value 
to  both  the  outside  groups  and  the  public  agency.  However,  the  advantages 
of  inside  information  and  symbolic  cooperation  with  government  that 
accrue  to  the  outside  group  are  probably  outweighed  by  the  implicit  limi- 
tations upon  freedom  to  criticize;  the  emotional  and  physical  strains  upon 
the  group  representative;  and  the  unpleasantness  of  being  open  to  charges 
from  the  group  itself  of  bureaucratic  sympathy  by  virtue  of  holding  a 
government  job.  If  the  administrative  job  is  worth  being  done,  it  would 
be  best  to  place  responsibility  upon  the  administrator  for  making  appoint- 
ments on  the  basis  of  individual  qualifications  in  relation  to  the  job  to  be 
done;  urge  him  to  seek  as  varied  as  possible  a  basis  of  social  experience, 
training,  and  personality  in  recruiting  his  staff;  permit  him  to  create  the 


330  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

healthy  and  necessary  unity  of  effort  that  arises  from  willing  cooperation 
in  an  organization  with  high  morale;  expose  him  to  outside  policy  pressures1, 
and  compel  him  to  inform  his  public  as  to  what  he  is  doing.  It  will  pay, 
however,  to  protect  him  from  ideological  conflict  within  his  own  staff. 

4.  INTEREST  REPRESENTATION  ON  ADMINIS  NATIVE  BOARDS 

Membership  Requirements.  Practical  politicians  and  political  scientists 
are  well  aware  of  the  opportunity  for  representation  of  group  interests  when 
public  agencies  are  headed  by  boards  instead  of  by  single  administrators. 
Specifically,  economic  group  representation  may  here  be  concealed  by  the 
qualification  of  appointees  as  party  members — usually  stated  in  terms  of  a 
limitation  upon  the  appointing  authority  that  no  more  than  two  members 
of  a  three-man  board  or  three  of  a  five-man  board  shall  belong  to  the  same 
political  party.  This  leaves  the  chief  executive  ample  discretion  to  nominate 
candidates  acceptable  to  him,  subject  to  the  advice  and  approval  of  party 
organizations  expressed  informally  as  well  as  through  one  or  both  houses 
of  the  legislature.14  Painstaking  analysis  of  the  biographical  history  and 
administrative  record  of  such  appointees  will  show  how  many  of  them  tend 
to  favor  particular  group  demands,  but  it  may  also  reveal  considerable  inde- 
pendence of  thought  and  refusal  to  follow  lines  of  group  cleavage  under 
conditions  of  relative  permanence  of  tenure.15 

Specific  representation  for  economic  groups  has  been  tried  spasmodically 
in  the  establishment  of  regulatory  tribunals.  Demands  for  it  are  associated 
with  the  idea  that  those  responsible  for  wielding  powers  of  such  vital  con- 
cern should  have  practical  knowledge  of  the  problems  of  the  regulated 
groups.  The  legislative  method  is  to  insert  a  statutory  provision  that  mem- 
bers of  the  board  or  commission  shall  be  appointed  as  bankers,  workers, 
businessmen,  and  farmers,  or  with  experience  in  defined  occupations.  These 
provisions  are  found  more  frequently  in  state  laws  than  in  federal  legisla- 
tion, and  there  has  been  no  general  federal  tendency  toward  adopting  such 
requirements,  for  several  reasons. 

The  appointing  chief  executive  can  take  the  element  of  vocational  ex- 
perience into  account  without  formal  limitation  in  the  law.  Moreover,  legis- 
lators wish  geographic  and  political  affiliations  to  be  considered  as  well. 
If  the  chief  executive  has  a  particular  candidate  in  mind,  he  can  usually  find 
technical  ways  to  meet  the  legal  qualification.  The  legislature  or  the  group 
interests  therefore  cannot  ensure,  as  a  matter  of  law,  that  their  candidates 

14  Cf.  Herring,  Pendleton,  Federal  Commissioners,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press, 
1936;  Zeller,  Belle,  Pressure  Politics  in  New  Yor%,  New  York:   Prentice-Hall,  1936;  McKean, 
D.  D.,  Pressures  on  the  Legislature  of  New  Jersey.  New  York:   Columbia  University  Press,  1938. 

15  C.  H.  Pritchctt's  studies  of  the  voting  record  of  the  Supreme  Court  led  him  to  conclude 
that  the  major  line  of  division  between  the  justices  is  *'the  allowable  extent  of  public  controls 
versus  private  rights."    This  issue  of  principle  transcends  and  cuts  across  lines  of  group  con- 
flict except  insofar  as  some  groups  maintain  a  consistently  antigovernmental  or  status  quo 
position.  See  'The  Divided  Supreme  Court,"  Michigan  Law  Review,  1945.  Vol.  44,  pp.  434-442. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  331 

will  be  selected.  It  is  constitutionally  doubtful,  as  well  as  undesirable  from 
the  angle  of  public  policy,  for  the  legislature  to  exercise  the  power  of  nomi- 
nating the  appointee.  Hence,  if  an  organized  group  cannot  succeed  in  tying 
the  chief  executive's  hand  by  this  method,  it  may  prefer  not  to  alienate 
him  by  a  halfway  step  and  rather  approach  him  through  informal  and 
political  channels.  In  the  case  of  proposals  for  bipartisan  representative 
boards,  the  group  making  the  demand  must  anticipate  counterdemands  from 
other  groups,  with  the  implicit  inference  that  a  balance  of  power  would 
be  lodged  in  a  public  representative  uncontrolled  by  any  group.  The  con- 
sequences of  permanently  implanting  such  a  conflict  in  administrative 
bodies  should  give  pause  to  outside  groups  interested  in  effective  and  prompt 
procedural  action.16 

Nomination  by  Interest  Groups.  A  third  device,  which  may  be  either 
formal  or  informal,  is  to  provide  for  appointment  by  the  chief  executive 
upon  nomination  by  interest  groups.  This  is  the  method  by  which  most 
state  professional  examining  boards  are  appointed.  In  a  nonpolitical  con- 
text, it  amounts  to  permitting  professional  groups  virtually  to  appoint  their 
candidates  and  fix  the  technical  standards  of  entrance  to  their  trade  or 
profession.  The  line  between  the  political  and  nonpolitical  is  easily  crossed, 
however,  and  such  agencies  move  carefully  to  secure  legislative  authoriza- 
tion for  their  tests  and  sanctions  in  granting  or  revoking  certificates  to 
practice.17 

In  establishing  public  corporations  the  British  have  used  variations  of 
the  device  of  formal  nomination  by  group  organizations  to  avoid  "political" 
influences  or  control  by  government  departments,  and  to  secure  the  advan- 
tages of  technical  experience  on  the  boards  of  directors.  The  governing 
board  of  the  Port  of  London  Authority  is  composed  of  eighteen  members 
elected  by  shipowners,  merchants,  rivercraft  owners  and  wharfingers,  and 
ten  members  appointed  by  public  authorities.  Of  the  public  authorities' 
appointments,  two  are  generally  representatives  of  union  labor.  The  Central 
Electricity  Board  of  seven  members  is  appointed  by  the  Minister  of  Trans- 
port after  consultation  with  such  interest  representatives  as  he  thinks  fit — that 
is  to  say,  local  government,  electricity,  commerce,  industry,  transport,  agri- 
culture, and  labor.  The  London  Passenger  Transport  Board  is  appointed 
by  an  ad  hoc  independent  body  of  appointing  trustees,  composed  of  the 
chairman  of  the  London  County  Council,  the  president  of  the  Law  Society, 
the  president  of  the  Institute  of  Chartered  Accountants  in  England  and 
Wales,  the  chairman  of  the  Committee  of  London  Clearing  Banks,  and  a 
representative  of  the  London  and  Home  Counties  Traffic  Advisory  Com- 
mittee. There  are  two  common  elements  in  British  methods  of  appoint- 
ment through  group  organizations:  (1)  creation  of  a  public  agency  to  do 

1<J  On  this  whole  question,  see  Leiscrson,  A  very,  Administrative  Regulation,  Chicago:  Uni- 
versity of  Chicago  Press,  1942. 

17  For  a  general  discussion,  see  below  Ch.  15,  "Legislative  Control." 


332  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

a  job  without  "political"  interference;  and  (2)  deliberate  representation  of 
many  interests  in  order  to  prevent  any  one  line  of  conflict  from  predominat- 
ing, thus  creating  a  situation  in  which  managerial  responsibility  must  be 
recognized. 

Bipartisan  and  Tripartite  Boards.  The  outstanding  governmental  func- 
tion in  which  the  representative  board  has  been  used  time  and  again  is 
the  settlement  of  labor  disputes.  In  spite  of  repeated  disappointments,  the 
demand  for  a  bipartisan  or  tripartite  board  directly  nominated  by  employer 
groups  and  unions,  with  or  without  participation  of  "the  public,"  some- 
how always  recurs.  The  reasons  seem  to  lie  in  part  in  the  complexities  of 
employer-union  relations,  the  facts  of  which  are  known  better  to  the  parties 
than  to  "outside"  mediators  or  arbitrators;  the  disinclination  to  allow  govern- 
ment agencies  to  administer  any  policy — however  named — of  compulsory 
arbitration  that  might  control  the  terms  of  the  labor  bargain;  the  familiar 
custom  and  pattern  in  negotiation  to  be  personally  represented  on  the  deci- 
sion-making body  when  the  policy  settlement  is  unclear;  and  the  desire  of 
many  labor  leaders  for  status  and  prestige  arising  from  participation  in 
governmental  policy-making. 

It  is  here  necessary  to  introduce  distinctions  or  functional  differentiations 
which  complicate  the  problem  but  are  essential  to  full  understanding.  Bi- 
partisan boards,  composed  of  an  equal  number  of  employer  and  union  rep- 
resentatives, have  functioned  successfully  for  many  years  in  the  arbitration 
of  collective  bargaining  demands.  However,  they  operate  quite  differently 
when  the  problem  is  one  of  working  out  the  details  of  applying  an  existing 
agreement,  or  of  deciding  general  policy  questions  such  as  those  of  the 
proper  level  of  wages  and  whether  union  membership  should  be  a  condition 
of  employment.  An  analogy  might  be  drawn  in  distinguishing  between  the 
problem  of  administering  a  provision  that  railroad  freight  rates  shall  apply 
faiily  and  equitably  to  different  classes  of  shippers,  and  the  problem  of 
raising  or  lowering  the  general  level  of  freight  rates  or  changing  the  dif- 
ferentials between  classes  of  shippers. 

If  the  purpose  of  public  policy  is  to  throw  primary  responsibility  for 
settling  disputes  back  upon  employers  and  unions,  a  bipartisan  board  may 
be  appropriate.  When  the  parties  themselves  have  failed,  as  in  disputes  over 
proposed  changes  in  labor  agreements  or  negotiation  of  new  agreements, 
another  element  is  injected.  It  is  the  requirement  that  a  public  agency  shall 
intervene,  either  to  mediate  the  dispute  by  recommending  formally  to  the 
parties  a  basis  of  settlement,  or  to  decide  authoritatively  the  terms  of  set- 
tlement. In  these  situations,  representation  of  the  disputants  upon  the  pub- 
lic body  tends  to  inhibit  rather  than  promote  a  free  formulation  of  the  issues 
in  terms  from  which  agreement  might  be  developed.  Bipartisan  or  tripartite 
boards  dealing  with  problems  of  changing  general  policy  therefore  invite 
continuance  of  settled  lines  of  dispute,  and  tend  to  throw  the  burden  of 
decision  on  the  public  or  neutral  members  of  the  board.  All  this  is  well 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  333 

known.  Yet  because  unions  do  not  wish  compulsory  settlement  of  labor 
disputes,  they  are  recurrently  urging  bipartisan  or  tripartite  representation 
on  governmental  labor  boards. 

Record  of  Wartime  Labor  Boards.  The  National  Defense  Mediation 
Board  (March-December,  1941)  and  the  National  War  Labor  Board  (1942- 
1945)  are  our  most  recent  and  dramatic  case  studies  of  tripartite  representa- 
tion. The  first  had  four  representatives  of  labor  and  employers,  and  three 
public  members;  the  second  had  four  representatives  for  each  of  the  three 
groups.  After  an  excellent  record  of  settling  disputes  by  recommending 
wage  increases — facilitated  by  government  defense  contracts — the  Defense 
Mediation  Board  fell  apart  when  the  CIO  members  resigned  because  the 
public  members  refused  to  recommend  a  union  shop  for  the  coal  mines 
operated  by  the  steel  companies. 

The  shock  of  Pearl  Harbor  caused  a  reorientation  of  the  board's  thinking. 
At  the  National  War  Labor  Policies  Conference  in  December,  1941,  a  no- 
strike,  no-lockout  pledge  was  secured  from  labor  and  management.  President 
Roosevelt  added  a  third  condition — that  the  renamed  National  War  Labor 
Board  would  be  empowered  to  settle  all  disputes.  Thereafter,  the  board 
operated  on  the  theory  that  some  form  of  security  would  have  to  be  given 
unions  in  return  for  renouncing  the  $trike  for  the  duration  of  the  emergency. 
A  maintenance-of-membership  clause  with  a  15-day  withdrawal  period 
was  the  formula  finally  decided  upon.  As  the  employer  representatives 
did  not  resign  from  the  board,  the  public  members  were  entitled  to  infer 
that  the  difference  between  industry  and  labor  had  been  "narrowed"  from 
an  "impassable  gulf"  to  an  acceptable  solution  of  the  conflict.18 

The  government's  wage  stabilization  policy,  announced  in  April,  1942, 
and  the  adoption  in  October  of  the  Economic  Stabilization  Act,  brought 
new  difficulties  upon  the  board.  The  "Little  Steel"  formula  was  adopted  in 
July  over  the  dissent  of  the  labor  members,  but  they  did  not  resign.  On 
the  contrary,  they  found  that  it  was  still  possible  to  secure  wage  increases, 
and  under  the  board's  wage  policies  of  November  6,  1942,  increases  were 
in  some  cases  agreed  upon  by  the  employer  and  union  representatives  that 
placed  the  public  members  in  a  dissenting  minority.  The  "Hold-the-Line" 
executive  order  of  April  8,  1943,  stopped  this,  but  the  union  members  re- 
mained. Now  another  element  of  friction  entered.  The  executive  order 
had  made  the  director  of  Economic  Stabilization  superior  to  the  board  in 
policy  review  and  coordination,  interfering  with  its  freedom  to  apply  the 
wage  stabilization  policy  to  the  decision  of  disputes  in  its  own  discretion. 
The  necessary  relationships  between  the  public  members  of  the  board  and  the 
Economic  Stabilization  director  became  a  serious  issue  to  the  labor  members, 
some  of  whom  openly  charged  the  latter  official  with  "politically"  interfering 

18  Davis,  William  H.,  "Aims  and  Policies  of  the  National  War  Labor  Board,"  Annals  of 
thf  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1942,  Vol.  224,  p.  145. 


334  INTEREST  CROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

with  board  responsibility  and  with  controlling  the  decisions  of  the  public 
members. 

Test  of  Interest  Compromise.  The  real  test  of  the  representative  adminis- 
trative board,  however,  lies  in  its  success  in  resolving  policy  problems  by 
compromising  the  differences  between  the  groups  represented  on  it.  The 
great  compromise  that  the  War  Labor  Board  brought  about  was  the  ac- 
quiescence of  employers  in  the  policy  of  maintenance  of  union  membership 
and  the  cooperation  of  organized  labor  with  wage  stabilization.  We  must 
admire  the  accomplishment  of  the  public  members  in  holding  the  board 
together,  and  thereby  maintaining  an  enormously  important  symbolic  unity 
between  labor  and  management  during  the  war  period.  It  may  safely  be 
stated,  however,  that  it  was  only  the  exigencies  of  war  that  induced  labor 
and  industry  to  accept  the  wage  stabilization  program. 

Students  of  the  internal  procedures  within  the  board  will  notice  the 
delays  and  backlogs  of  cases  due  to  the  refusal  of  employer  and  union 
members  to  accept  policy  decisions  of  the  board  as  precedents  in  handling 
new  cases.  Here,  once  more,  the  verdict  of  history  will  decide  whether  the 
recognition  of  basic  interests  and  the  preservation  of  external  unity  were 
worth  the  price  of  administrative  delays  and  suspension  of  the  processes 
of  collective  bargaining.  The  contention  that  the  War  Labor  Board  ad- 
vanced collective  bargaining  and  developed  a  legacy  of  policy  which  unions 
and  employers  would  wish  to  preserve  after  the  war  went  up  in  smoke 
within  sixty  days  after  Japan  surrendered.  Both  parties  seem  quite  united 
on  keeping  government  out  of  labor  disputes.  Yet  we  may  question  whether 
this  attitude  will  be  permanent,  and  whether  tripartite  representation  would 
not  again  be  requested  if  governmental  intervention  in  specifying  the  terms 
of  the  labor  bargain  were  to  become  imminent. 

5.  THE  PRINCIPLE  OF  CONSULTATION 

General  Theory  of  Interest  Representation.  At  this  point,  the  outlines  of 
the  general  theory  of  interest  representation  may  briefly  be  sketched.  The 
underlying  idea  is  .best  described  by  the  phrase  "economic  federalism,"  in 
the  sense  of  a  division  of  authority  and  function  between  government  and 
the  broad  economic  groupings  in  which  men  and  women  spend  most  of 
their  working  hours  and  derive  their  personal  appreciation  of  the  political 
process.  The  ethical  foundation  of  the  concept  is  found  in  the  importance 
of  creating  in  the  community  as  wide  as  possible  a  basis  of  training  and 
experience  in  governmental  affairs,  and  of  the  deeper  unity  arising  from  a 
commonly  shared  sense  of  contribution  in  solving  social  problems.  The 
theory  appeals  to  social  democrats  because  of  its  justification  of  autonomous 
group  life,  and  perhaps  also  because  it  is  ambiguous  enough  to  apply  to 
three  different  forms  of  institutional  arrangements,  enabling  its  exponents 
to  substitute  one  for  another  without  being  politically  inconsistent.  The 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  335 

chree  organizational  concepts  are  excellently  illustrated  in  the  writings  of 
Professor  Harold  J.  Laski. 

In  World  War  I,  during  a  period  in  his  life  of  observation  and  specula- 
tion on  a  relatively  abstract  plane,  Laski  was  greatly  impressed  with  the 
importance  of  permitting  voluntary  groups  such  as  unions  and  churches 
a  high  degree  of  freedom  to  select  and  pursue  their  objectives  under  organ- 
ized government  dominated  by  private-property  attitudes.19  Later,  in  his 
Grammar  of  Politics?®  Laski  rejected  a  constitutional  structure  based  upon 
autonomous  groups  wielding  powers  of  both  economic  and  political  de- 
cision. He  substituted  for  this  form  of  federalism  a  concept  of  group  rep- 
resentation and  consultation  at  policy  levels  of  public  administration,  wisely 
allowing  such  details  as  the  degree  of  policy-making  authority  and  the 
selection  of  representatives  to  vary  with  the  nature  of  the  administrative 
problem.  During  the  ensuing  twenty  years,  Laski  reflected  on  both  the 
menace  of  fascism  and  the  internal  divisions  within  the  Western  democra- 
cies that  inhibited  the  formation  of  an  aggressively  democratic  program. 
After  entering  active  politics,  he  has  come  to  emphasize  the  importance 
of  a  unifying  democratic  faith.  The  contribution  of  economic  groupings  to 
such  a  faith  cannot  be  a  matter  of  autonomous  choice.  It  must  be  made 
in  cooperation  with  government  through  a  uniting  symbol  of  the  most 
inclusive  good — namely,  the  program  of  a  freely  elected  people's  party.21 

Basic  Distinctions  in  Group  Representation.  We  can  now  see  that  the 
concept  of  economic  group  representation  allows  distinctions  as  to:  (1)  the 
level  of  policy  determination — that  is  to  say,  the  area  and  scope  of  govern- 
mental jurisdiction  over  which  general  decisions  of  economic  policy  should 
be  made  and  within  which  local  or  functional  differentiations  should  be 
permitted;22  (2)  the  recognition  of  power  groups  and  other  interests  in 
general  policy  formation;  and  (3)  the  method  of  organizing  the  process  by 
which  interest  participation  should  be  guaranteed.  The  problem  involved 
in  the  first  distinction  is  clearly  one  of  paramount  political  and  legislative 
policy.  Any  attempt  to  solve  such  questions  by  the  exercise  of  adminis- 
trative power  simply  throws  the  administrative  agency  into  the  middle  of 
political  controversy  that  a  higher  political  authority  should  decide,  unless 
it  be  assumed  that  politics  and  administration  are  one. 

The  problem  arising  from  the  second  distinction  refers  in  part  to  the 
constitutional  guarantees  and  rights  of  free  association,  petition,  and  assem- 
bly. However,  it  blends  into  the  administrative  sphere  when  an  agency 
is  given  discretion  to  select  and  define  the  group  categories  or  organizations 

19  Foundations  of  Sovereignty,  "Administrative  Areas"  and  "The  Pluralistic  State,"  espe- 
cially p.  75  #.,  New  York:  Harcourt  Brace,  1921. 

20  Ch.  2,  and  pp.  282-285,  384-387,  New  Haven:   Yale  University  Press,  1925. 

21  Faith,  Reason  and  Civilization,  New  York:  Viking,  1944. 

22  Paul  Appleby  has  pointed  out  that  from  a  management  standpoint  it  is  nonsense  to 
decentralize  until   central   policy   integration  has  been  attained.    Op.  cit.  above  in   note   11, 
pp.  100-102. 


336  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION 

whose  interests  it  desires  to  take  into  account.  This  problem  may  be 
summed  up  by  saying  that  powerful  group  organizations  can  usually  get 
their  views  presented.  The  difficulty  of  administrators  is  to  maintain  a  clear 
understanding  that  their  public  responsibility  is  broader  than  their  allegiance 
to  any  one  group.  Their  responsibility  requires  consideration  of  general 
governmental  policy  and  the  interests  of  the  community  as  a  whole. 

Organization  of  Interest  Participation.  The  scope  of  this  chapter  has 
been  in  general  restricted  to  the  third  problem,  which  can  be  restated  as  the 
question  of  how  to  take  into  account  the  views  of  all  relevant  group  inter- 
ests in  administrative  policy-formation.  We  have  analyzed  several  organiza- 
tional devices  and  found  each  somehow  unsatisfactory.  This  seems  to  be 
due  to  two  factors.  First,  while  administrative  discretion  affords  an  oppor^ 
tunity  for  groups  to  press  for  favorable  determination  of  policy  questions 
that  are  not  yet  legislatively  settled,  most  groups  fail  to  realize  that  an  ad- 
ministrative agency  cannot  attempt  to  decide  larger  controversial  issues  with- 
out risking  its  own  security  through  political  conflict.23  Second,  interest 
groups  often  fail  to  recognize  that  they  may  want  fairness  and  impartiality 
in  administration  even  more  than  they  want  a  share  of  official  responsibility 
for  policy  determination. 

The  vital  problem  of  how  to  bring  interest-group  influences  to  bear  upon 
the  process  of  administrative  policy-formation  is  not  a  simple  matter  of 
calling  conferences  and  holding  hearings.  The  sense  of  participation  is  es- 
sential to  social  or  public  morale,  but  this  is  not  automatically  secured  by 
formal  arrangement.  It  must  be  developed  and  learned  by  creating  a  set  of 
understood  conditions,  special  skills,  and  mutual  responsibilities  on  the  part 
of  the  group  members,  their  leaders,  the  administrator,  and  his  staff.  When 
these  specifications  have  been  met  and  the  participants  have  learned  how 
to  promote  their  separate  interests  by  working  together,  some  form  of  the 
advisory  committee  will  be  found  most  acceptable  to  all.  The  reason  is  ob- 
vious. If  we  assume  that  consent  is  necessary  to  the  administrator  and  that 
group  interests  wish  to  be  freely  and  independently  represented,  the  incen- 
tive should  be  placed  upon  the  administrator  to  win  group  assent,  and  the 
group  representatives  should  be  free  to  withdraw  and  to  criticize.  Three 
wartime  examples  are  pertinent. 

Three  Wartime  Examples.  The  first  example  is  drawn  from  the  experi- 
ence of  the  Office  of  Defense  Transportation,  which  set  up  an  advisory  com- 
mittee composed  of  representatives  of  railroad  management  and  labor  to 
consider  wartime  measures  of  conservation  and  efficiency.  Such  measures 
necessitated  revision  of  treasured  union  rules  embodied  in  established  union 
agreements.  ODT,  for  reasons  best  known  to  its  staff,  chose  by  order  to  ab- 
rogate rules  prescribing  the  length  of  trains.  While,  in  the  light  of  wartime 

28  The  proper  distinction  is  that  administrators  need  not  be  neutral  in  their  recommenda- 
tions on  forward-looking  policy  changes  and  should  contribute  actively  to  their  decision,  but 
should  not  decide  themselves. 


INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTRATION  337 

conditions,  the  unions  might  have  delivered  up  their  dearly  prized  rules, 
the  ract  remains  that  the  abrogation  worked  to  the  pecuniary  advantage  of 
the  carriers,  who  sought  to  escape  from  the  conditions  of  bargaining  agree- 
ments under  the  guise  of  lofty  principle.  As  a  consequence,  the  union  mem- 
bers of  the  ODT  advisory  committee  resigned  and  sought  redress — obtained 
subsequently — through  direct  negotiations  with  the  carriers.  And  ODT 
lost  a  channel  for  securing  the  cooperation  of  the  railroad  unions  in  its 
wartime  tasks. 

The  second  example  is  the  Management-Labor  Policy  Committee  of  the 
War  Manpower  Commission.  The  committee  went  through  two  stages: 
(1)  1942-1943,  when  as  a  bipartisan  labor-management  board  it  practically 
ran  WMC;  (2)  1943-45,  when  it  was  reorganized  to  include  representatives 
of  agriculture  and  to  place  highest-ranking  officials  of  the  great  national 
labor,  business,  and  farmer  organizations  on  the  committee.  The  effect  of 
the  shift  was  that  the  committee  was  somewhat  less  frequently  consulted 
and  had  less  to  do  with  administrative  detail. 

Nevertheless,  in  both  stages  the  committee  members  agreed  and  insisted 
that  voluntary  methods  should  be  relied  upon  to  control  the  flow  of  man- 
power into  essential  civilian  industries  and  occupations.  By  and  large, 
the  government  followed  this  policy  throughout  the  war,  except  for  moral 
pressure  exerted  through  publicity  and  advertising  and  through  "paper" 
controls  such  as  employment  stabilization  plans  and  centralized  referrals 
to  jobs  in  each  community  through  the  employment  offices,  and  the  col- 
lateral control  of  wages  by  the  War  Labor  Board.  If  any  general  criticism 
of  wartime  governmental  manpower  policy  may  be  made,  it  is  that  the 
War  Manpower  Commission  and  its  chairman  failed  to  formulate  a  posi- 
tive program,  on  the  one  hand  permitting  the  military  agencies  to  fix  their 
own  manpower  requirements,  on  the  other  following  a  separate  policy  with 
respect  to  the  requirements  of  nonmilitary  employers  of  labor. 

The  third  example  is  the  wartime  policy  of  the  British  Minister  of 
Labor.  Ernest  Bevin  established  a  joint  consultative  committee  composed  of 
representatives  selected  by  the  Employers'  Confederation  and  the  Trades 
Union  Congress.  This  committee  did  not  attempt  to  assume  responsibility 
for  determining  Briush  manpower  policy.  The  government  initiated  and 
sponsored  the  drastic  powers  assumed  by  it  in  the  Essential  Work  Orders- 
in-Council,  but  it  took  pains  to  initiate  consultations  with  the  joint  commit- 
tee on  every  step  and  change  of  policy  while  these  were  being  formulated.24 
Apparently  the  same  procedures  were  not  followed  in  planning  for  military 
demobilization,  however.25  Although  the  Minister  in  charge  of  reconver- 
sion planning,  Lord  Woolton,  advised  the  committee  that  demobilization 


24  Sec  Radcliffe,  J.  V.,  "Trade  Unions'  Part  in  Britain's  War  Effort,"  Annals  of  the  American 
Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1942,  Vol.  224,  pp.  117-123. 

25  British  Trades  Union  Congress,  Report  of  General  Council,  pp.   161-162,   Blackpool, 
1944. 


338  INTEREST  GROUPS  IN  ADMINISTOATION 

plans  were  at  an  advanced  stage,  he  refused  to  indicate  their  general  outlines 
or  principles.  The  Minister  of  Labor  informed  the  committee  that  he  was 
"not  in  a  position"  to  give  any  indication  of  the  government's  plans.  The 
General  Council  of  the  Trades  Union  Congress  then  formally  told  the 
Prime  Minister  that  a  violation  of  the  principle  of  consultation  had  taken 
place.  The  Prime  Minister's  reply,  made  more  than  two  months  later, 
stated  that  the  demobilization  policy  should  first  be  announced  to  Parlia- 
ment. The  deterioration  of  consultative  relationships  reflected  in  this  de- 
cision of  Winston  Churchill  may  well  have  had  a  bearing  not  only  on  the 
quality  of  civilian  morale  but  also  on  the  withdrawal  of  the  Labor  Party 
from  the  government  in  less  than  a  year. 

(Foundations  of  Interest  Consultation.  These  three  applications  of  the 
principle  of  consultation  do  not  demonstrate  once  and  for  all  its  superiority 
over  other  forms  of  "shared  participation"  in  public  policy-making.  They 
illustrate  the  workings  of  a  cooperative  arrangement  which  places  priority 
of  importance  upon:  (1)  mutual  respect  for  responsibilities  of  administrat- 
ors and  group  leaders;  (2)  working  with  others  rather  than  allowing  one 
group  to  put  something  over  on  the  others  that  they  don't  have  to  take; 
(3)  fair  dealing  by  making  information  available  on  purposes  and  methods 
of  administration  within  the  defined  scope  of  the  plan;  and  (4)  providing 
opportunity  for  criticisms  and  suggestions.  The  principle  of  consultation 
on  the  administrative  level  clearly  will  not  appeal  to  those  who  assume 
that  their  views  must  be  adopted  or  they  won't  play.  It  will  work  only 
under  conditions  where  the  participants  assume  that  a  process  of  expert 
investigation  and  open  discussion  is  the  proper  way  to  discover  the  best 
means  of  realizing  an  agreed-upon  public  purpose. 

He  who  is  more  interested  in  influencing  the  formulation  of  that  purpose 
is  simply  expressing  his  legitimate  preference  for  participation  in  political 
conflict  rather  than  for  reducing  political  decisions  from  debatable  hypotheses 
to  administrative  operations.  It  is  confusion  thrice-confounded  to  carry 
such  conflict  into  the  administrative  process  and  to  make  administrative 
organization  the  arena  for  continuing  political  battles.  Unless  we  decide 
to  delegate  governmental  powers  to  a  single  political  group  which  can  only 
be  overthrown  by  violence,  we  must  assume  that  tentative  solutions  to 
our  social  and  economic  conflicts  can  from  time  to  time  be  reached  by  those 
skilled  in  winning  the  people's  votes,  who  will  turn  over  to  those  trained 
in  administratioiy(he  task  of  seeing  to  it  that  the  terms  of  political  settlements 
are  made  to  work, 


CHAPTER 


15 


Legislative  Control 

1.  MEANS  AND  CONDITIONS  OF  CONTROL 

Central  Issue  of  Governance.  The  distinctive  institution  of  popular  gov- 
ernment is  the  representative  assembly.  But  representative  assemblies  alone 
cannot  govern.  The  power  to  lead  in  policy-making  and  to  direct  adminis- 
tration must  be  vested  in  a  chief  executive.  Although  popular  authority 
may  rest  in  the  representative  assembly,  an  aggregation  of  five  hundred 
men  and  women  in  a  hall  does  not  constitute  a  government.  / 

In  democracies,  one  of  the  fundamental  constitutional  problems  is  that 
of  the  relations  between  the  representative  body  and  the  executive  branch. 
Unfettered  and  uncontrolled  power  may  gravitate  to  executive  agencies  if  the 
popular  body  is  weak.  On  the  other  hand,  if  inadequate  power  is  vested 
in  the  executive  branch,  government  may  follow  a  faltering  and  hesitant 
policy,  at  times  with  risk  to  national  survival.  If  the  representative  body 
attempts  to  assume  the  executive  function,  it  tends  to  become  a  market  place 
where  individuals  and  factions  bargain  away  the  national  welfare  for 
sectional  or  parochial  gain. 

Our  scheme  of  separated  powers  creates  peculiar  difficulties  in  the  adjust- 
ment of  relations  between  the  executive  branch  and  the  representative  body. 
By  design,  the  constitutional  system  assures  rivalry — and  therefore  friction — 
between  them;  by  checks  and  balances  it  laces  both  together  in  inescapably 
close  relations.  Not  only  do  we  have  the  frictions  inevitable  between  the 
legislature  and  the  chief  executive,  each  independent  and  equal.  In  addi- 
tion, the  administrative  departments  are  caught  between  the  rival  claims 
of  both. 

Members  of  Congress  often  declaim  in  tones  of  irritation  that  the  bu- 
reaucrats ought  to  keep  in  mind  their  responsibility  to  the  elected  repre- 
sentatives of  the  people.  Yet  the  bureaucrat  knows  that  through  a  definite 
hierarchy  of  control  he  is  accountable  to  the  President,  who  under  the 
Constitution  is  the  chief  executive  vested  with  powers  of  direction.  More- 
over, the  President  as  well  as  Congress  is  chosen  by  the  people— a  fact  often 
disregarded  in  the  bickering  of  lawmaker  and  executive.  Although  it  rarely 

339 


340  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

arises  in  such  bald  form,  the  question  often  distills  down  in  particular  cases 
to  whether  the  President  or  Congress  shall  direct  the  administrative  agencies 
in  the  execution  of  the  laws.  The  forces  polarized  around  this  issue 
permeate  the  e-itire  executive  structure  and  account  for  many  of  the  basic 
characteristics  of  American  public  administration. 

Formal  Means  of  Legislative  Control.  Although  we  speak  of  "legis- 
lative control"  of  administration,  our  constitutional  theory  does  not  con- 
template that  the  chief  executive  will  be  subservient  to  the  legislative  body. 
Legislative  supremacy  requires  that  the  tenure  of  the  principal  executive 
officers  depend  on  the  will  of  the  representative  body.  In  our  system, 
both  the  legislature  and  the  chief  executive  have  ill-defined  spheres  of  dom- 
inance. Legislative  influence  manifests  itself  in  the  process  of  relating  the 
functions  of  legislative  and  executive  organs.  Denied  the  formal  power  to 
designate  the  chief  executive  and  the  heads  of  executive  agencies,  legislators 
seek  to  influence  the  direction  of  administrative  policy  by  other  means. 

The  principal  formal  means  in  the  hands  of  Congress  for  control  of 
the  administration  are  the  powers  of  enacting,  amending,  and  repealing 
legislation,  of  investigation,  and  of  appropriation.  In  addition,  the  Senate 
has  the  right  to  review  presidential  appointments,  except  those  to  "inferior 
offices,"  which  are  vested  in  the  President  or  the  heads  of  departments. 
These  types  of  formal  authority  are  not  all  the  means  of  legislative  control; 
the  fact  that  formal  powers  exist  and  may  be  used  enables  Congress  and  its 
members  to  exert  great  influence  by  such  methods  as  criticism  from  the 
floor,  or  through  press  statements  and  by  personal  contact  and  individual 
pressure.  Each  administrative  agency  keeps  a  sharp  eye  on  congressional 
attitudes  and  often  trims  its  sails  accordingly. 

The  mere  mention  of  these  legislative  powers  indicates  their  significance 
as  means  of  control  of  administration.  Acts  of  Congress  fix  the  limits  of 
power  which  may  be  exercised  by  administrative  agencies,  and  often  the 
manner  of  its  exercise.  Moreover,  authority  which  is  granted  may  be  with- 
drawn. Administrators  must  proceed  on  the  assumption  that  the  legislation 
they  administer  may  be  repealed  or  modified.  However,  the  power  of 
repeal  is  difficult  to  exercise;  opportunities  for  obstruction  in  the  legislative 
process  are  many,  and  a  repealing  act  must  be  signed  by  the  President  or 
passed  over  his  veto. 

In  recent  years,  a  method  has  been  developed  by  which  Congress  can 
virtually  repeal  a  law  without  the  possibility  of  defeat  by  Presidential  veto. 
Many  emergency  acts  of  World  War  II  were  to  remain  in  effect  until  six 
months  after  the  end  of  the  war,  until  a  date  specified  in  the  act,  or  "until 
such  earlier  time  as  the  Congress  by  concurrent  resolution  or  the  President 
may  designate."  Concurrent  resolutions  are  not  submitted  to  the  President 
for  approval.  Hence  a  means  has  been  invented — though  of  untested 
constitutionality— by  which  Congress  can  in  effect  repeal  legislation  or  with- 
draw powers  from  administrative  agencies  without  the  danger  of  a  presi- 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  341 

dential  veto.1  While  no  case  of  use  of  this  power  has  occurred,  the  very 
existence  of  the  power  is  not  without  its  effect  within  the  executive  branch. 

Congress  exercises  even  more  effective  control  over  administration  by 
enacting  legislation  to  be  effective  for  only  one  year  or  for  some  other  de- 
terminate period.  Administrative  policy  and  performance  may  therefore  be 
reviewed  by  Congress  when  an  extension  of  power  is  sought.  For  months 
preceding  the  renewal  of  such  an  act,  its  administrators  walk  warily,  per- 
haps fearing  to  take  steps  of  urgent  importance  lest  some  group  in  Congress 
be  annoyed.  The  reciprocal  trade-agreement  program  provides  an  example 
of  an  administrative  activity  based  on  limited-term  legislation.  Many  im- 
portant war  activities — for  instance,  price  control,  priorities,  selective  service — 
were  based  on  short-term  legislation.  Administrators  must  wage  battle 
for  renewal  when  the  expiration  dates  of  such  statutes  approach.  The 
difficulty  of  obtaining  positive  action  from  Congress  gives  to  congressional 
opponents  of  a  policy  based  on  short-term  legislation  certain  advantages 
which  they  do  not  enjoy  under  ordinary  legislative  forms. 

The  appropriating  process  is  the  most  comprehensive  and  the  most 
systematic  means  by  which  the  legislature  reviews  administrative  activities. 
Once  a  year  administrators  must  appear  before  the  subcommittees  of  the 
two  Appropriations  Committees  and  explain  and  justify  in  great  detail  their 
requests  for  money.  They  must  answer  questions — some  penetrating,  some 
sympathetic,  some  unfriendly — about  their  operations.  Once  a  year  they 
are  on  the  carpet  and  must  be  prepared  to  defend  their  work  against  what- 
ever criticism  the  members  of  the  Appropriations  Committees  feel  disposed 
to  make.  In  the  course  of  the  hearings,  legislative  instructions  are  often 
given  which,  while  not  written  into  the  appropriation  act,  are  regarded  as 
binding.2 

Looking  Into  Particulars.  The  power  of  investigation  is  in  theory  a 
method  by  which  Congress  obtains  information  on  which  to  base  legislation. 
In  fact,  it  tends  to  be  in  the  main  a  method  by  which  Congress  directs 
public  attention  to  particular  administrative  situations  and  makes  its  wishes 
known  to  administrators.  Many  varieties  of  investigations  are  conducted 
by  congressional  committees.  In  some  instances,  resolutions  grant  commit- 
tees full  power  to  compel  the  attendance  of  witnesses  and  the  production 
of  records  and  papers.  In  others,  a  quorum  of  a  standing  committee  decides 
to  conduct  an  inquiry  and  requests  the  appearance  of  administrators.  In 
some  instances,  the  inquiry  is  conducted  with  the  assistance  of  a  competent 
staff  which  does  the  spadework  necessary  to  prepare  for  an  informative 
public  hearing.  In  others,  committee  members  depend  on  their  own  per- 
sonal knowledge  for  an  offhand  interrogation  of  the  witnesses.  In  motive 
the  inquiry  may  be  a  sincere  and  responsible  effort  to  promote  the  public 

1  See  White,  Howard,  "Executive  Responsibility  to  Congress  via  Concurrent  Resolution,'1 
American  Political  Science  Review,  1942,  Vol.  36,  pp.  895-900. 

2  Consult  the  excellent  analysis  by  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  "Congressional  Oversight  o* 
Administration:    The   Power   of   the   Purse,"   Political  Science  Quarterly,   1943,  Vol.  58,  pp 
161-190.  380-414. 


342  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

good.  Or  it  may  be  simply  designed  to  discredit  individuals  or  programs 
in  an  unfair  manner.3 

From  time  to  time  Congress  virtually  assumes  administrative  functions 
by  acting  on  individual  cases  rather  than  in  terms  of  general  principles. 
Thus  an  appropriation  act  of  1944  provided  that  "prior  to  the  acquisition 
or  disposal,  by  lease  or  otherwise,  of  any  land  acquired  for  naval  use  under 
the  authority  of  this,  or  any  other  act,  the  Secretary  of  the  Navy  shall  come 
into  agreement  with  the  Naval  Affairs  Committees  of  the  Senate  and  of 
the  House  of  Representatives  with  respect  to  the  terms  of  such  prospective 
acquisitions  or  disposals.  .  .  ."4  Similarly,  the  Alien  Registration  Act  of 
1940  provided  that  the  Attorney  General  should  deport  immediately  any 
alien  whose  deportation  had  been  suspended  more  than  six  months  if  the 
"two  Houses  pass  a  concurrent  resolution  stating  in  substance  that  the 
Congress  does  not  favor  the  suspension  of  such  deportation."  Congressional 
participation  in  individual  administrative  actions,  however,  is  more  gen- 
erally accomplished  by  less  formal  methods. 

Atomization  of  Control.  The  existence  of  all  these  powers  in  the  legis- 
lative body  is  elementary.  The  conditions  of  their  exercise  are  matters 
less  well  understood.  Congress,  House  of  Representatives,  and  Senate  are 
terms  evoking  in  the  mind  the  notion  of  an  assembly  that  debates,  delib- 
erates, and  decides.  Such  notions  must  be  supplemented  by  more  adequate 
conceptions  if  we  are  to  comprehend  the  interplay  between  legislature  and 
administration.  Congress  as  a  whole  can  really  master  and  decide  only 
a  few  main  issues.  So  great  is  the  volume  of  legislative  business  and  such 
are  our  parliamentary  practices  that  we  have  in  reality  not  one  legislative 
body  but  scores  of  small  legislative  bodies.  When  we  seek  to  understand 
the  relations  of  Congress  with  the  executive  branch,  we  must  speak,  not 
of  either,  but  of  this  Senator,  or  that  Representative,  or  this  committee,  or 
that  bloc  and  the  administrative  establishment.  The  actions  of  Congress 
are  in  the  great  majority  of  instances  those  of  a  single  member,  or  two,  or 
a  handful — actions  which  their  colleagues  ratify  or  to  which  they  raise 
no  objection. 

The  committee  system  accords  great  power  to  a  few  individuals  in 
Congress.  Our  Congress  does  not  have  the  great  fear  of  committees  that 
some  representative  bodies  manifest.  Committees  are  not  regarded  with 
jealousy  as  groups  that  grasp  and  exercise  the  power  of  the  entire  body, 
but  as  the  normal  media  for  doing  business.  Consequently,  committee 
chairmen  in  particular  are  very  powerful.  Their  power  is  greater  for  ob- 
struction than  for  initiation;  nonetheless  it  is  formidable.  If  a  measure 
goes  through  the  committee,  its  chances  of  adoption  are  good.  If  the  com- 


8  See  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  Congressional  Investigating  Committees,  Baltimore:  Johns 
Hopkins  Press,  1929;  McGeary,  M.  N.,  The  Developments  of  Congressional  Investigative  Power, 
New  York:  Columbia  University  Press,  1940. 

458  Stat.  189. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  343 

mittee  is  hostile,  the  measure  is  almost  certain  to  die  in  spite  of  the  occa- 
sional invocation  of  the  discharge  rule  to  compel  the  committee  to  report 
the  bill. 

Weakness  of  Legislative  Discipline.  Power  is  not  only  dispersed  within 
the  representative  body;  beyond  that,  the  individuals  of  influence  also  are 
not  necessarily  in  agreement  with  each  other  or  with  the  dominant  views 
of  the  majority  party.  The  choice  of  committee  chairmen  is  ordinarily 
determined  by  seniority  of  service,  and  the  secret  of  success  in  Congress 
lies  in  a  combination  of  horse-sense,  luck,  and  longevity.  A  committee 
chairman,  though  belonging  to  the  party  headed  by  the  President,  may 
therefore  be  completely  at  outs  with  the  general  policy  of  the  government. 
Thus,  in  a  critical  period  in  World  War  II,  the  chairman  of  the  Senate 
Military  Affairs  Committee  was  quite  hostile  toward  the  principal  phases 
of  our  defense  policy.5  The  major  parties  in  House  and  Senate  have  dis- 
covered no  way  to  bring  such  dissenters  into  line  with  the  general  party 
program  or  prevent  their  selection  for  committee  posts.  Nor  has  the  House 
or  Senate  found  a  way  to  discipline  the  few  irresponsible  members  who 
bring  the  lawmaking  body  as  a  whole  into  disrepute  by  stupid  or  dema- 
gogic actions.  So  weak  is  legislative  discipline,  yet  so  strong  is  the  spirit 
of  fraternity,  that  a  member  can  scarcely  provoke  his  brethren  to  raise  their 
voices  in  protest  and  in  defense  of  the  good  name  of  Congress. 

Legislative  usages  ensure  that  divergences  of  view  exist  between  the 
executive  branch  and  at  least  some  of  the  principal  centers  of  power  in 
Congress.  The  rule  of  seniority  tends  to  give  committee  chairmanships  and 
other  positions  of  influence  to  members  from  sections  most  faithful  to  one 
party.  Members  from  such  areas,  Democratic  or  Republican,  are  likely 
to  have  a  different  outlook  on  public  policy  than  has  the  President,  who 
must  orient  his  policy  toward  the  middle  of  the  road  or  politically  doubtful 
areas.  But  the  actual  pattern  of  power  in  Congress  is  both  complicated 
and  kaleidoscopic.  Only  to  authors  of  textbooks  on  civics  are  our  legis- 
latures simple  affairs.  The  student  of  comparative  institutions  finds  in 
them  elements  of  an  English  municipal  council,  with  its  close  committee 
relations  with  administrative  agencies;  the  Chamber  of  Deputies  of  the 
French  Republic,  with  its  individualism  and  shifting  majorities;  the  House 
of  Commons,  with  its  party  solidarity — all  interlarded  with  a  liberum  veto 
of  an  indigenous  variety.6 

Because  of  the  internal  workings  of  Congress  the  actual  pattern  of  re 
lations  between  Congress  and  the  executive  branch  is  incredibly  complex 
For  the  purposes  of  the  present  analysis,  it  is  essential  to  note  the  power 
of  the  individual  and  of  the  small  group  within  Congress  with  respect  to 


5  See  Davis,  Burke,   "Senator  Bob  Reynolds:    Retrospective  View,"  Harper's,  Vol.  186, 
March,  1943,  pp.  362-369. 

6  One  of  the  best  single  volumes  on  Congress  is  Roland  Young's  This  Is  Congress,  New 
York:  Knopf,  1943. 


344  LEGISLATIVE   CONTROL 

the  great  mass  of  congressional  business,  and  the  diversity  of  policy  views 
among  these  centers  of  power. 

2.  CONTRADICTION  OF  INTEGRATION 

Absence  of  Collective  Administrative  Responsibility.  A  basic  concept 
of  administrative  speculation  of  the  past  thirty  years  is  that  of  integration. 
The  idea  has  organizational  implications  but  it  also  includes  the  notion 
that  the  chief  executive  must  so  direct  the  administrative  agencies  that 
interagency  conflict  of  objectives  is  minimized.  Different  agencies  should 
administer  related  programs  in  a  complementary  fashion  and  will  do  so 
only  by  conscious  top  direction.  The  administrative  structure  is  unified 
under  the  chief  executive.  The  general  concept  of  integration  also  carries 
with  it  the  notion  of  unified  legislative  programs  for  administrative  agencies. 
Departments  should  move  forward  in  the  same  direction  as  well  as  be 
managed  in  their  current  operations  in  a  coordinated  manner.  Examples 
are  legion.  One  agency  should  not  promote  inflationary  spending  while 
another  promotes  deflationary  taxation.  Another  should  not  try  to  drain 
land  for  agricultural  use  while  still  another  attempts  to  preserve  the  same 
swamps  as  game  habitats. 

Congress,  in  its  relations  with  the  executive  branch,  tends  to  atomize 
rather  than  integrate  the  administrative  structure  and  public  policy.  A 
factor  of  prime  importance  in  this  tendency  is  the  practical  absence  of  any 
custom  or  sense  of  collective  responsibility  within  the  administrative  estab- 
lishment. Each  department  head  must  stand  on  his  own  feet.  Important 
blocs  in  Congress  may  conduct  guerilla  warfare  against  him.  Ordinarily, 
he  must  fight  his  own  battle.  His  colleagues  do  not  rally  to  his  cause;  they 
are  not  endangered.  If  he  is  in  the  good  graces  of  Congress  at  the  moment, 
he  must  shape  his  policy  on  the  supposition  that  if  he  should  run  counter 
to  the  interests  of  the  legislators  most  concerned  with  his  program,  he  would 
have  to  fight  for  himself.  The  President  will  usually  stand  aloof,  for  in 
the  presidential  system  there  is  an  element  reminiscent  of  the  constitu- 
tional monarchy — the  President  must  to  some  extent  remain  outside  the 
political  fray. 

The  fact  of  individual  responsibility  is  of  the  most  profound  admin- 
istrative significance.  It  throws  the  agency  head  into  the  arms  of  the  con- 
gressional committees  and  blocs  having  a  particular  interest  in  the  activities 
of  his  agency,  and  puts  him  at  the  mercies  of  whatever  groups  are  involved. 
Administrative  departments,  both  because  of  their  internal  drives  and  ex- 
ternal affiliations,  tend  to  be  particularistic.  Integration  must  proceed  from 
the  President,  and,  to  be  effective,  it  must  curb  the  departments  and  the 
interests  allied  with  them. 

Under  presidential  leadership  a  great  deal  of  administrative  unification 
may  be  accomplished  on  so-called  noncontroversial  matters.  However,  on 
questions  of  basic  importance  the  agency  must  sooner  or  later  weigh  the 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  345 

advantages  of  faithfully  going  down  the  line  of  presidential  policy  against 
the  disadvantages  of  antagonizing  a  small  but  powerful  group  in  Congress. 
Thus,  a  Secretary  of  Agriculture  who  recognized  that  the  consumer  of 
food  has  an  interest  in  its  price  would  probably  be  reprimanded  from  the 
floor  of  Congress  and  be  given  rough  treatment  by  the  producer-minded 
committees  on  agriculture.  So  he  might  merely  pay  lip  service  to  an  in- 
tegrated economic  policy. 

Or,  let  us  consider  the  various  efforts  by  the  President  to  unify  operations 
in  the  development  and  control  of  water  resources.  The  Bureau  of  Reclama- 
tion of  the  Interior  Department  and  the  Army  Corps  of  Engineers  are 
great  competitors  in  this  field.  Each  has  its  allies  in  Congress.  Only  so 
far  and  no  farther  can  the  President  go  in  coordinating  the  two  agencies, 
because  the  friends  of  each  unite  to  deny  funds  to  the  President  to  employ 
staff  for  coordinating  purposes.  Under  these  conditions,  the  sense  of  col- 
lective responsibility — the  feeling  that  ours  is  a  government  rather  than  a 
fortuitous  grouping  of  departments — does  not  make  itself  strongly  felt. 
Yet  such  a  consciousness  is  requisite  for  the  development  of  the  most  ef- 
fective coordination  and  integration  of  administrative  operations. 

Splintering  Effects  of  Legislative-Executive  Relations.  The  strong  cen- 
trifugal tendencies  in  an  administrative  structure  organized  to  a  large 
extent  on  a  clientele  basis  are  reenforced  by  the  dispersion  of  congressional 
authority  among  many  working  centers.  The  practice  of  individual  re- 
sponsibility of  department  heads  is  one  manifestation  of  the  confluence  of 
these  institutional  and  social  factors.  However,  the  splintering  effects  of 
our  system  of  congressional-executive  relationships  extend  farther  down 
into  the  administrative  machine.  The  position  of  department  heads  is  often 
weakened  by  direct  dealings  between  Congress  and  the  chiefs  of  depart- 
mental subdivisions. 

Hierarchical  control  within  the  departments  is  modified  by  a  variety 
of  practices.  Probably  one  of  the  most  significant  is  the  custom  in  con- 
gressional criticism  of  placing  the  finger  of  responsibility  on  bureau  chiefs 
and  other  subordinates  of  department  heads.  Not  infrequently  speeches 
of  Congressmen  or  their  press  conferences  ring  with  denunciations  of 
these  subordinate  departmental  officials.  Or,  such  officials  receive  congres- 
sional praise  for  their  wise  and  statesmanlike  management  of  affairs.  The 
practice  in  either  instance  has  the  same  effect — an  erosion  of  intradepart- 
mental  controls.  The  general  problem  is  well  illustrated  in  a  negative  way 
by  the  reply  of  the  Chief  of  Naval  Operations  to  a  question  by  the  Senate 
Naval  Affairs  Committee  on  the  Greer  incident  in  1941 :7 

Q.  Are  there  any  reasons  why  the  commanding  officer  and  other 
officers  and  men  of  the  Greer  should  not  appear  before  the  committee? 
If  so,  what  are  those  reasons? 

A.  Yes.    Testimony  of  such  officers  would  be  almost  certain  to  dis- 

7  Congressional  Record,  Vol.  87,  p.  8314. 


346  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

close  vital  military  secrets  which  would  endanger  other  naval  vessels. 
In  addition,  to  establish  a  precedent  or  to  have  naval  officers  at  sea  feel 
that  whenever  they  take  action  they  would  or  might  be  called  before  a 
congressional  investigating  committee  to  explain  and  justify  their  action, 
would  be  prejudicial  to  the  conduct  of  operations  on  the  high  seas. 

Legislative  Dealings  with  Subordinate  Personnel.  Direct  congressional 
dealings  with  subordinates  in  the  review  of  appropriation  requests  have 
something  of  the  same  effect.  The  department  head  may  put  in  a  brief 
appearance  at  the  beginning  of  the  hearings.  However,  members  of  Con- 
gress prefer  to  talk  with  the  men  down  the  line  who  actually  do  the  work, 
and  perhaps  in  the  course  of  the  interrogation  give  them  instructions  on 
how  the  job  ought  or  ought  not  to  be  done  in  the  future. 

A  bureau  chief  is  "strong"  or  "weak"  in  dealing  with  Congress — "on 
the  Hill."  If  "strong,"  he  may  be  brought  into  line  in  an  integrated  de- 
partmental program  only  with  difficulty.  Bureau  chiefs  may  become  quite 
independent  of  the  heads  of  their  agencies  insofar  as  broad  policy  is  con- 
cerned. This  independence  is  usually  associated  with  their  status  "on  the 
Hill"  or  with  outside  interest  groups.  Likewise,  the  manner  in  which 
appropriations  are  sometimes  made  may  have  a  similar  effect.  The  appro- 
priation may  be  made  to  a  particular  bureau  rather  than  to  the  department. 
Under  these  conditions,  departmental — and  occasionally  presidential — di- 
rection may  be  met  by  the  reply:  "But  we  are  responsible  to  Congress  for 
the  manner  in  which  this  program  is  carried  out."8 

The  close  connections  between  members  of  Congress  and  bureau  chiefs 
frequently  promote  stability  and  continuity  in  policy  and  are  by  no  means 
invariably  detrimental  to  the  general  welfare.  These  relations,  however, 
make  it  difficult  for  the  President  or  Congress  to  hold  department  heads 
accountable  for  the  management  of  their  affairs.  Bureau  chiefs  and  senior 
legislators  are  the  cream  of  the  career  crop  in  the  federal  government. 
Both  groups  are  likely  to  regard  Presidents  and  department  heads  as  tran- 
sient trespassers.  Probably  the  greatest  resistance  to  direction  by  depart- 
ment heads  is  to  be  found  in  the  highly  professionalized  services — in 
particular,  the  military  services.  It  is  indeed  an  unusual  Secretary  of  the 
Navy  or  Secretary  of  War  who  can  make  much  of  an  impress  upon  his 
department. 

Congressional  supervision  of  departments  occasionally  extends  to  mass 
examination  of  the  qualifications,  antecedents,  and  affiliations  of  subordin- 
ate personnel.  Such  inquiries  may  be  quite  impersonal  witch-hunting 
expeditions  with  no  specific  animosity  toward  any  particular  employee.  In 
some  instances  congressional  reaction  reaches  the  point  of  formal  measures 

8  On  the  general  question  of  congressional  control  of  executive  agencies,  see  Herring, 
Pendleton,  "Executive-Legislative  Responsibilities/'  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944, 
Vol.  38,  pp.  1153-65. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  347 

to  ensure  the  discharge  of  designated  individuals.9  These  practices  have 
an  insidious  effect  on  the  work  of  subordinate  personnel.  An  employee's 
spine  may  become  spaghetti-like  when  there  exists  the  possibility  of  his 
being,  in  effect,  blacklisted  for  federal  employment  through  denunciation 
by  individual  lawmakers  simply  for  doing  his  duty. 

Subtler  Legislative  Influences.  All  these  interferences  with  hierarchical 
control  have  been  described  in  a  manner  which  colors  the  exposition  to  a 
degree  with  exaggeration.  In  reality,  the  tendencies  are  more  subtle  and 
more  difficult  to  identify  than  our  discussion  might  lead  us  to  believe.  The 
significance  of  these  practices  may  be  best  comprehended  by  comparison 
with  the  customs  of  British  cabinet  government.  The  responsible  minister 
is  the  man  who  must  answer  on  the  floor  of  Parliament  for  the  misdeeds 
of  his  department.  He  cannot  dodge  the  brickbats,  and,  in  compensation, 
he  has  a  monopoly  of  the  bouquets.  He  can  be  held  accountable  only  if 
he  alone  can  hold  his  subordinates  accountable.  He  therefore  must  make, 
or  appear  to  make,  the  policy  decisions.  The  concentration  of  criticism 
upon  the  responsible  minister  has  a  most  pervasive  intradepartmental  effect 
in  tightening  up  the  internal  lines  of  control,  supervision,  and  communi- 
cation.10 All  this,  of  course,  is  not  the  same  as  saying  that  the  United  States 

9  See   Cushman,   Robert  E.,    "The   Purge   of  Federal   Employees  Accused  of  Disloyalty," 
Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  pp.  297-316;  Schuman,  Frederick  L.,  '"Bill  of 
Attainder'  in  the  Seventy -Eighth  Congress,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1943,  Vol.  37, 
pp.  819-29.    Section  304  of  the  Urgent  Deficiency  Appropriation  Act  of  1943  provided:    "No 
part  of  any  appropriation,  allocation,  or  fund  (1)  which  is  made  available  under  or  pursuant 
to  this  act,  or  (2)  which  is  now,  or  which  is  hereafter  made,  available  under  or  pursuant  to 
any  other  act,  to   any  department,  agency,  or  instrumentality  of  the  United  States,  shall  be 
used,  after  November  15,  1943,  to  pay  any  part  of  the  salary,  or  other  compensation  for  the 
personal  services,  of  Goodwin   B.  Watson,   William  E.  Dodd,  Jr.,  and  Robert  Morss  Lovett, 
unless  prior  to  such  date  such  person  has  been  appointed  by  the  President,  by  and  with  the 
advice  and  consent  of  the  Senate.  .  .  ."    With  the  approval  of  their  respective  superiors  these 
three  men  continued  to  perform  their  duties  after  November  15,  1943,  and  sued  to  collect  their 
salaries.    The  Court  of  Claims  upheld  their  claim  for  compensation.   The  opinion  of  the  court, 
delivered  by  the  Chief  Justice  and  concurred  in  by  one  judge,  held  that  the  act  did  not  operate 
to  remove  the  plaintiffs  from  office  and  that  they  were  entitled  to  collect.   In  separate  opinions 
concurring  in   the  result,   the  other  judges  of  the  court  went  further  and  asserted  that  the 
congressional  action  was  unconstitutional.    Different  judges,  however,  had  different  reasons  for 
considering  the  provision  invalid.    The  Supreme  Court  held  Sec.  304  void;  U.  S.  v.  Lovett, 
Watson,  and  Dodd,  June  3,  1946. 

10  In  1943  a  Canadian  labor  leader  attacked  the  chairman  of  the  War  Prices  and  Trade 
Board,  characterizing  him  as  "Canada's  No.  1  Nazi."   The  chairman  was  a  subordinate  of  the 
Minister  of  Finance  and  was  thus  comparable  to  a  bureau  chief  or  other  similar  subordinate 
official  in  the  United  States.    It  is  difficult  to  conceive  of  an  editorial  like  the  following  being 
published  as  a  consequence  of  such  an  incident  in  the  United  States: 

"This  we  suggest  is  a  case  where  a  word  is  needed  from  some  voice  in  the  Government. 
This  Montreal  labor  man  is  more  likely  than  not  an  irresponsible  flannel -mouth;  speaking  no 
more  for  labor  than  for  the  rest  of  us.  The  trouble  is  that  thousands  of  people  throughout  the 
country  may  not  consider  him  a  flannel-mouth,  will  take  what  he  says  seriously.  .  .  . 

"Mr.  Gordon  and  the* War  Prices  Board  are  merely  an  administrative  agency.  They  do 
not  make  laws;  they  administer  them.  They  carry  out  duties  and  functions  given  them  by 
Parliament  and  the  Government,  and  for  which  Parliament  and  the  Government  must  take  full 
responsibility. 


348  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

should  have  a  cabinet  government.  It  is  only  a  means  of  illuminating  by 
contrast  the  character  of  the  influences  at  work  under  a  system  of  separa- 
tion of  powers. 

Grants  of  Organizational  Independence.  In  some  types  of  situations, 
action  by  Congress  has  more  direct  effects  in  the  atomization  of  adminis- 
tration than  the  more  or  less  subtle  influences  described.  Examples  fre- 
quently occur  in  connection  with  organization.  Thus,  legislation  which 
establishes  a  function  independent  of  the  department  to  which  it  might 
fall  in  the  normal  course  has  long-term  administrative  consequences.  The 
new  agency,  uninfluenced  by  such  forces  of  integration  as  flow  from  in- 
corporation into  a  department,  is  left  free  to  pursue  its  own  inclinations. 
More  important,  it  is  likely  to  be  politically  weak,  especially  dependent  on 
interest-group  support,  and  unable  to  take  a  strong  stand  in  its  dealings  with 
legislative  blocs.  It  may  become  something  of  an  administrative  orphan, 
buffeted  about  by  the  political  storms. 

In  the  independent  regulatory  commission  there  occurs  the  most  striking 
splintering  of  administration  by  legislative  action.  In  a  deliberate  effort  to 
make  them  independent  of  the  chief  executive,  such  agencies  are  declared 
to  be  "responsible"  to  Congress.  The  fact  of  the  matter  is  that  they  are 
responsible  to  no  one.  They  may  keep  their  ears  close  to  congressional  com- 
mittees, but  Congress  is  not  organized  to  enforce  a  continuing  responsi- 
bility. 

The  chances  are  that  a  regulatory  commission  dealing  with  a  single 
industry  will  be  more  nearly  responsible  to  the  industry  than  to  the  legis- 
lature. Deprived  of  the  influences  on  policy  that  flow  from  give-and-take 
with  other  departments  and  from  the  directions  of  the  chief  executive,  the 
independent  commission  gravitates  toward  an  industry  point  of  view.  More 
or  less  from  necessity  it  seeks  to  retain  the  confidence  of  the  regulated  in- 
dustry. Indeed,  the  theory  on  which  the  commissions  are  based  makes  it 
impracticable  for  them  to  collaborate  with  the  chief  executive  or  other  execu- 
tive agencies  in  the  development  of  a  unified  policy.  Their  quasi-judicial 
procedure  renders  it  improper  for  them  to  commit  themselves  to  a  general 

"In  England  there  is  an  old,  well-established  tradition  under  which  members  of  the  Cabinet 
take  responsibility  for — and  defend — the  acts  of  their  officials.  It  is  an  integral  part  of  the 
principle — also  observed  scrupulously — under  which  officials  themselves  make  no  statements  on 
policy,  and  engage  in  no  public  controversy. 

"That  principle  should  operate  in  Canada.  Our  cabinet  ministers,  and  the  Government  as 
a  whole,  cannot  be  permitted  to  take  credit  to  themselves,  for  the  prices  ceiling  and  the  War 
Prices  Board,  yet  remain  silent,  let  others  take  the  blame,  when  officials  of  the  War  Prices 
Board  are  abused  and  vilified. 

"In  the  circumstances,  we  suggest  it  is  up  to  the  appropriate  member  of  the  Cabinet  to 
tell  the  country  that  if  there  is  dictatorship  under  the  War  Prices  Board  Administration  the 
dictatorship  belongs  to  the  Government,  or  to  Parliament;  that  if  any  charge  of  'Nazism*  be 
made  it  should  be  made  against  the  Government  and  Parliament.  In  other  words,  whatever 
responsibility  exists  should  be  fixed  properly."  Ottawa  Morning  Journal,  September  3,  1943. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  349 

policy  lest  they  thereby  prejudice  themselves  in  the  determination  of  par- 
ticular cases. 

All  in  all,  the  legislative  forces  playing  on  the  administrative  structure 
contribute  to  disintegration  in  management.  In  effect  legislators  seek  to 
exercise  piecemeal  the  function  of  direction  over  administration.  Legis- 
lators who  are  jealous  of  chief  executives,  either  in  particular  or  in  general, 
find  this  a  congenial  role.  In  reality,  however,  legislative  control  is  most 
effective  when  all  administration  is  sufficiently  integrated.  In  appropria- 
tions, for  example,  lawmaking  bodies  are  most  effective  when  the  chief 
executive  presents  a  well-considered  and  carefully-pruned  budget.  Under 
such  conditions,  the  estimates  become  a  tool  of  legislative  oversight.11 

In  other  areas,  legislative  influences  on  administration  are  generated  in  no 
slight  measure  from  the  weakness  of  the  chief  executive.  The  power  of  the 
chief  executive  is  usually  described  in  awesome  terms.  In  actual  fact,  the 
administrative  apparatus  at  his  command  to  aid  him  in  knowing  what  is 
going  on  below  his  level  and  in  guiding  operations  is  quite  inadequate. 
This  is  in  part  the  result  of  legislative  jealousy  of  the  executive,  but  what- 
ever the  origin,  the  lawmaking  branch  moves  in  to  occupy  as  well  as  it 
may  the  administrative  vacuum. 

3.   DIFFUSION  OF  INITIATIVE  AND  RESPONSIBILITY 

Executive  Share  in  Policy-Making.  Legislation  fixes  the  scope  of  ad- 
ministrative power  and  to  a  large  degree  the  manner  of  its  exercise.  Laws 
must  be  constantly  adjusted  to  meet  changed  conditions  and  to  reflect  ex- 
perience in  their  application.  The  administration  in  power  must  inevitably 
have  an  important  share  in  the  formulation  of  legislative  measures.  In 
our  executive-legislative  relationships  we  have  made  little  provision  for  an 
honest  recognition  of  this  necessity. 

Administrators  participate  in  the  formulation  of  legislation,  but  their 
activities  are  to  a  degree  surreptitious  and  always  subject  to  the  accusation 
of  constitutional  immorality.  If  the  chief  executive  proposes  legislation,  he 
is  charged  in  many  instances  with  attempting  to  coerce  a  coequal  govern- 
mental organ  and  of  leading  the  nation  along  the  road  to  dictatorship.  He 
may  find  it  advisable  to  refrain  from  action  when  he  should  exercise  strong 
leadership.  On  the  other  hand,  since  he  will  risk  little  if  Congress  rejects 
his  proposal,  he  may  urge  legislation  which  he  knows  Congress  will  not 
enact.  Thereby  he  gains  credit  with  some  sectors  of  the  population.  Simi- 
larly, he  may  ease  his  duty  by  placing  a  problem  before  Congress  and 
leaving  to  that  body  the  unhappy  choice  of  means  to  solve  the  problem.  Or 
he  may  for  a  long  time  neglect  an  urgent  problem  and  present  to  Congress 
no  proposed  solution.  No  legislature  is  able  to  develop  and  put  into  effect 


11  See  Smith,  Harold  D.,  "The  Budget  as  an  Instrument  of  Legislative  Control  and'  Execu- 
tive Management,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  181-188. 


350  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

a  comprehensive  legislative  program  on  its  own  initiative.  Nor  does  it  have 
any  recourse  against  the  chief  executive  if  he  fails  to  exercise  leadership. 

Desertions  From  the  President's  Program.  Our  unhappy  state  of  execu- 
tive-legislative relationships  in  the  formulation  and  adoption  of  general  pro- 
grams results  in  halting  and  uneven  progress  in  the  adaptation  of  the  legal 
framework  within  which  administration  must  operate.  The  legislative  pro- 
gram of  the  chief  executive  no  less  than  the  administrative  structure  tends 
to  be  devoid  of  unity.  Administrative  drives  to  unify  the  legislative  program 
encounter  the  obstacle  of  relatively  weak  internal  direction  as  well  as  the 
check  of  strong  ties  between  particular  departments,  groups,  and  blocs 
within  Congress.  Each  department  head  prefers  to  be  free  to  promote  his 
own  legislative  objectives  in  Congress.  In  turn  he  is  encouraged  in  this 
preference  by  Congressional  protagonists  of  his  agency. 

Freedom  of  departmental  initiative  in  appropriation  matters  is  limited  by 
the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921,  which  prohibits  federal  depart- 
ments from  seeking  funds  in  sums  larger  than  those  recommended  by  the 
President  in  his  annual  budget  or  any  supplement.  Administrative  agencies, 
however,  can  usually  manage  to  get  their  wishes  on  record  through  the  in- 
terposition of  friendly  Congressmen.  The  situation  is  illustrated  by  the  fol- 
lowing interchange  in  1945  between  Mr.  Tarver,  a  member  of  the  House 
Appropriations  Committee,  and  Mr.  Jones,  the  War  Food  Administrator: 

Mr.  Tarver:  ...  I  have  noted  with  a  great  deal  of  misgiving  this  pro- 
posal of  the  Budget  to  cut  down  A.  A.  A.  funds  to  $290,000,000  and  to 
provide  for  a  further  cut  in  the  next  fiscal  year  to  $200,000,000.  .  .  .  Do 
you  feel  that  that  is  a  wise  course  of  procedure?  If  not,  what  are  the 
reasons  which  cause  you  to  arrive  at  your  conclusion? 

Mr.  Jones:  I  can  only  give  you  my  personal  opinion  on  those  matters 
because  we  submit  our  requests  to  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  and,  of 
course,  the  official  Budget  then  comes  up  to  Congress  by  way  of  an 
estimate.  I  do  not  hesitate  to  give  you  my  personal  opinion  on  these 
matters  if  you  wish  me  to  do  so. ... 

Mr.  Tarver:  I  would  be  very  glad  to  have  you  do  so. 

Mr.  Jones:  I  think  it  would  be  very  unfortunate  if  through  a  reduc- 
tion in  funds,  especially  at  this  critical  period  of  the  war,  the  A.  A.  A. 
is  handicapped. 

I  would  like  to  see,  if  it  were  left  to  me  personally,  full  provision  made 
by  direct  appropriation  for  soil-conservation  payments.  They  have  paid 
great  dividends.  There  is  no  question  about  it. 

Mr.  Tarver:  You  mean  for  $300,000,000? 

Mr.  Jones:  Yes.  That  is  what  I  personally  would  prefer.  I  am  giving 
you  just  my  personal  viewpoint.12 

In  other  instances,  the  battle  to  upset  the  President's  budgetary  recommenda- 
tions may  be  carried  by  private  organizations  which  are  in  very  close 
contact  with  the  administrative  agencies. 

12  House  Committee  on  Appropriations,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Hearings  on  Agriculture 
Department  Appropriation  Bill  for  1946,  pt.  2,  p.  10,  1945. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  J5l 

In  matters  other  than  appropriations,  federal  agencies  are  subject  to  the 
requirement  that  they  clear  with  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  proposed  legisla- 
tion and  comments  on  legislative  proposals.  The  clearance  process  serves  the 
purpose  of  determining  whether  the  views  of  the  agency  are  in  accord  with 
the  program  of  the  President.  Formal  agency  statements  to  Congress  are 
supposed  to  include  an  indication  of  the  relationship  of  the  matter  in  ques- 
tion to  the  President's  program.  The  procedure  results  in  a  modification  of 
some  legislative  ambitions  of  individual  agencies  and  an  early  death  to 
many  of  their  proposals.13  Yet  the  practice  of  coordination  of  such  legisla- 
tive urges  into  a  systematic  and  consistent  program  is  only  in  a  relatively 
embryonic  form.  Further  development  will  require  a  much  more  tightly 
knit  management  of  the  executive  branch  than  has  been  the  custom.  More- 
over, there  is  some  doubt  whether  such  a  condition  can  be  brought  about 
until  Congress  itself  ceases  to  encourage  autonomous  departmental  initiative 
in  legislation. 

Inadequate  Legislation.  Absence  of  cohesion  in  the  legislative  program 
of  the  chief  executive — absence  in  fact  of  a  program  clearly  designated  as 
such — contributes  mightily  to  confusion  in  the  public  mind,  to  submission 
of  ill-considered  legislative  proposals,  and  to  poor  administration.  Legis- 
lative schemes  emerging  from  the  departments  are  often  ill-conceived  and 
inadequately  thought  through.  Not  infrequently  the  scheme  worked  out  in 
a  single  department  raises  a  variety  of  questions  about  its  relationship  to 
other  governmental  activities.  In  fact,  Congress  has  to  devote  a  great  deal 
of  its  energies  to  the  settlement  of  interagency  disputes  on  issues  of  no  over- 
whelming public  importance  which  might  very  well  be  settled  within  the 
administrative  establishment. 

Our  ineffective  linking  of  the  administrative  and  legislative  processes 
has  important  consequences  in  the  operation  of  the  executive  branch.  Per- 
haps one  of  the  most  significant  is  the  necessity  of  operating  under  inade- 
quate or  inappropriate  legislation  which  hampers  or  limits  administration 
or  makes  it  ineffective  or  unduly  costly.  Government  agencies  hesitate 
to  seek  modifications  from  Congress.  They  will  rather  indulge  in  im- 
provisations and  patiently  endure  the  oddest  kinds  of  legal  limitation.  The 
reason  is  obvious.  They  never  know  what  will  emerge  from  the  legislative 
mill  once  it  begins  to  turn.  Except  for  the  most  important  questions  on 
which  broad  public  discussion  and  understanding  may  be  brought  to  bear, 
the  administrative  tendency  is  to  limp  along  on  the  existing  legal  basis, 
no  matter  how  unsatisfactory  it  may  be.  It  is  regarded  as  better  than  to 
arouse  sleeping  dogs. 

13  See  the  testimony  of  F.  J.  Bailey,  Chief  of  the  Division  of  Legislative  Reference,  Bureau 
of  the  Budget,  in  House  Committee  on  the  Civil  Service,  Hearings  pursuant  to  H.  Res.  16, 
pt.  2,  pp.  359-373,  78th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  1943.  See  also  Witte,  E.  E.,  'The  Preparation  of 
Proposed  Legislative  Measures  by  Administrative  Departments,"  in  President's  Committee  on 
Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Sttidies,  p.  361  #.,  Washington:  Government 
Printing  Office,  1937. 


352  LEGISLATIVE  CONTOOL 

Incongruity  Between  Power  and  Responsibility.  The  basic  fact  is  that 
we  have  an  institutional  system  which  does  not  assure  that  administration 
will  have  power  commensurate  with  its  responsibility.  Take,  for  instance, 
the  following  remarks  of  Senator  Connally  in  1940  during  the  considera- 
tion of  a  proposal  to  establish  a  joint  congressional  committee  on  national 
defense,  whose  consent  would  have  been  required  before  the  President 
might  make  expenditures  from  an  emergency  fund  for  national  defense: 

I  want  to  perform  my  responsibility  in  this  crisis  or  emergency.  I 
want  to  fill  the  place  in  my  country  that  my  countrymen  think  I  should 
fill,  and  perform  whatever  duty  is  laid  upon  me;  but  I  do  not  want  to 
take  over  somebody  else's  function  or  somebody  else's  responsibility. 
Give  the  President  this  $100,000,000.  He  has  the  responsibility;  but  if 
we  hamper  him,  if  we  impede  him,  if  we  embarrass  him  with  a  smelling 
committee,  we  lessen  his  responsibilities.  He  can  very  easily  say,  *I 
undertook  to  discharge  this  function,  but  every  time  I  sought  to  dis- 
charge it,  I  had  to  run  up  to  the  Capitol  and  talk  to  some  Members  of 
the  House  and  some  Senators  who  could  not  make  up  their  minds,  who 
delayed,  who  hindered,  and  who  undertook  to  interject  into  the  theories 
of  the  War  and  Navy  Department  policies  which  I  did  not  regard  as 
wise  or  sound/14 

Questions  of  like  character  are  implicit  in  almost  every  important  legis- 
lative proposal.  Perhaps  one  of  the  reasons  why  we  so  often  have  incon- 
gruity between  power  and  responsibility  is  that  Congress  has  no  routine 
means  by  which  it  can  hold  the  executive  branch  accountable  for  the  exer- 
cise of  its  power.  A  chief  executive  cannot  say  to  Congress:  "I  refuse  to 
accept  responsibility  for  results  on  the  terms  imposed  by  Congress.  I  resign 
and  yield  the  control  of  government  to  the  opposition."  Actions  of  Con- 
gress— keeping  in  mind  that  Congress  for  all  practical  purposes  means  this 
bloc,  this  committee,  and  even  this  member — thus  are  not  fraught  with  the 
danger  that  its  chickens  will  come  home  to  roost. 

The  legislative  bloc  from  livestock-producing  states,  for  instance,  which 
succeeds  in  raising  the  price  of  meat,  is  not  likely  to  be  placed  in  charge  of 
distribution  and  have  to  cope  with  the  complaints  of  processors  and  con- 
sumers. The  Congressman  who  succeeds  in  discrediting  the  Federal  Com- 
munications Commission  is  not  likely  to  have  an  opportunity  to  demon- 
strate that  he  can  do  any  better  in  regulating  the  broadcasting  industry. 
The  congressional  group  which  succeeds  in  boosting  the  price  of  milk  will 
not  in  the  normal  course  of  events  have  to  listen  to  disgruntled  urban 
housewives. 

Legislators  and  Administrators.  The  administrator  and  the  legislator 
move  in  different  environments  and  are  subjected  to  different  influences. 
The  administrator  often  derives  moral  satisfaction  from  the  fact  that  he 
looks  at  public  issues  in  a  context  different  from  that  in  which  they  are 
viewed  by  the  legislator.  He — so  the  theory  runs — considers  issues  in  terms 

14  Congressional  Record,  Vol.  86,  p.  6593. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  353 

of  the  national  welfare,  while  the  legislator  views  them  as  they  bear  on  his 
state  or  district.  In  this  contrast,  which  contains  at  least  a  grain  of  truth, 
the  administrator  has  no  cause  for  self-congratulation.  The  difference  arises 
from  the  institutional  structure.  The  voters  elect  their  representatives  to 
look  out  for  their  interests.  A  Senator  from  Nevada  cannot  very  well  be  a 
statesman  on  the  silver  issue,  just  as  a  Representative  from  a  coal-mining 
district  cannot  for  long  neglect  the  interests  of  his  constituents.  Moreover, 
administrators  themselves  have  their  prejudices.  The  Department  of  Agri- 
culture or  the  Department  of  Labor  and  those  who  manage  them  are  not 
free  from  bias  in  the  definition  of  the  national  interest. 

The  interaction  between  legislature  and  administration,  with  the  accom- 
panying division  of  power,  makes  it  quite  difficult  to  place  responsibility 
for  action  or  inaction.  The  legislator  can  tell  his  constituents  that  he  does 
his  best  to  keep  the  bureaucrats  from  doing  so  many  foolish  things.  The 
administrator  can  assert  that  he  is  doing  as  well  as  he  can  with  the  obstacles 
placed  in  his  path  by  Congress.  And  both  may  be  right. 

From  the  newspapers  we  may  gain  the  impression  that  legislators  are 
an  irresponsible  lot,  solely  concerned  with  promoting  the  selfish  causes  of 
their  own  districts.  The  picture  is  far  from  correct.  Every  Congress  has 
many  members  who  labor  earnestly,  diligently,  soberly,  and  steadily  to  pro- 
mote the  general  welfare,  as  they  see  it.  Their  activities  are  far  overshad- 
owed in  the  press  by  the  reports  of  the  animadversions  of  their  more  pic- 
turesque or  picaresque  colleagues.  The  heavy  routine  work  of  the  legislator 
does  not  produce  headlines.  Wild  charges  do.  Thus,  criticism  by  Congress 
of  the  executive  branch  takes  on  a  fantastic  character.  Since  such  criticism 
is  not  in  face-to-face  debate,  the  most  fabulous  allegations  may  be  made 
with  no  one  to  question  them. 

The  more  incredible  a  story,  the  more  attention  it  may  receive  in  the 
press;  such  is  often  the  editorial  standard  of  what  constitutes  news.  Nor 
does  the  public  receive  informative  reporting.  Thus,  a  news  lead  may  read: 
"  'The  Washington  corn  policy  constitutes  a  deliberate  and  calculated  effort 
by  this  power-hungry  government  to  drive  the  farmers  into  bankruptcy,' 
Senator  Doakes  of  Illiana  charged  today.  'It  is  another  step  on  the  road  to 
dictatorship  along  which  we  are  being  carried.  It  is  what  one  can  expect 
when  the  Department  of  Agriculture  is  staffed  with  Phi  Beta  Kappas  who 
have  never  slopped  a  hog.'  " 

More  accurate  reporting  might  make  the  story  read:  "The  corn  policy 
was  denounced  by  Senator  Doakes  of  Illiana.  The  Senator,  a  member  of 
the  minority  party,  owns  three  corn  farms,  comes  from  a  state  in  which 
corn-growing  is  the  principal  industry  and  will  be  up  for  reelection  this 
fall.  He  spoke  from  a  manuscript  prepared  at  the  national  headquarters  of 
the  Corn  Growers  League  of  which  he  is  a  past  president.  Seven  Senators 
were  on  the  floor  at  the  time;  they  appeared  to  be  unperturbed  by  his 
remarks." 


354  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

The  continuing  and  inevitable  attempts  of  Congress  to  manage  the  busi- 
ness of  administration  diffuse  responsibility  and  confuse  the  public.  In  strict 
administrative  theory  there  is  usually  nothing  but  condemnation  for  the 
interferences  of  Congress  with  administration — interventions  which  are 
usually  in  terms  of  particular  cases  or  local  interests  rather  than  of  general 
principle.  Congress— the  textbooks  argue— should  limit  itself  to  action  on 
general  rules;  then  the  individual  cases  would  take  care  of  themselves.  In 
some  respects,  however,  the  very  fact  that  lawmakers  do  criticize  and  inter- 
vene in  specific  cases  and  local  situations  makes  their  attacks  a  valuable 
corrective  to  administrative  generalization. 

It  is  sometimes  forgotten  that  ours  is  after  all  a  huge  country  with  citizens 
living  and  working  under  an  almost  infinite  variety  of  conditions.  There 
is  in  administration  an  almost  inevitable  tendency  to  reduce  action  to  gen- 
eral rules  and  to  treat  all  individual  situations  as  if  they  were  alike.  Legis- 
lators, in  their  capacity  as  ambassadors  for  their  constituents,  intercede  in 
individual  situations  and  demand  adaptation  of  administrative  practices  to 
fit  the  situation.  It  is  not  enough  to  dismiss  this  function  of  legislators  by  say- 
ing that  they  intervene  regardless  of  the  justice  of  the  cause  of  their  con- 
stituent. Generally  they  have  a  higher  sense  of  responsibility  than  that; 
and  since  they  cannot  be  ignored  they  may  and  often  do  bring  about  many 
correctives  of  administrative  action.  Wisdom  in  government  is  not  so  much 
the  formulation  of  just,  general  rules  as  the  making  of  judicious  exceptions 
therefrom.15 

4.   QUEST  FOR  ACCOUNTABILITY 

Selecting  Department  Heads.  Legislative  supremacy  means  that  the 
lawmaking  body  has  power  both  to  choose  the  principal  executive  officers 
and  to  terminate  their  services.  The  American  constitutional  system  does 
not  formally  provide  for  legislative  supremacy.  The  selection  and  tenure  of 
the  President  are  not  determined  by  legislative  action,  although  by  virtue  of 
their  role  in  party  affairs  Senators  and  Representatives  may  make  themselves 
felt  in  the  choice  of  presidential  nominees.  On  the  other  hand,  the  Presi- 
dent as  party  leader  is  not  without  influence  in  the  selection  of  members 
of  the  House  and  Senate. 

Nevertheless,  once  elected,  neither  the  President  nor  Congress  can  for- 
mally influence  the  tenure  of  office  of  the  other.  The  status  of  subordinate 
executive  officers  is  different  from  that  of  the  President.  There  is  a  con- 
tinuing effort  by  Congress  to  exert  control  over  their  appointment  and 
tenure.  These  efforts  are  based  in  part  on  the  formal  powers  of  Congress — 
such  as  the  power  of  the  Senate  to  confirm  presidential  nominations  to  cer- 
tain offices.  In  most  instances,  however,  the  legislature  seeks  to  determine 

16  For  extended  treatment  of  the  problems  touched  on  here,  see  Herring,  Pendleton,  Presi- 
dential Leadership,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1940;  Laski,  Harold  J.,  The  American 
Presidency,  New  York:  Harper,  1940. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  355 

the  top  personnel  of  the  executive  branch  by  indirection.  The  President 
also  has  to  choose.  When  two  governmental  organs  attempt  to  select  the 
holders  of  the  same  offices,  conflict  is  inevitable. 

The  power  to  designate  and  discharge  the  principal  executive  officers  is 
probably  the  most  effective  means  of  controlling  administration.  Both  the 
chief  executive  and  the  legislature  have  a  variety  of  devices  for  determining 
what  is  to  be  done  and  how  it  is  to  be  done.  However,  it  is  far  easier  to 
guide  the  general  direction  of  administrative  business  by  the  choice  of  chief 
officers  whose  viewpoints  are  of  the  desired  type.  Congress  wants  to  in- 
fluence these  choices.  Its  efforts  subside  and  flare  up  from  time  to  time  as 
the  general  temperature  of  attitudes  toward  the  chief  executive  fluctuates. 

In  a  broad  sense,  our  principal  executive  and  administrative  officers  must 
retain  the  confidence  of  Congress  just  as  the  ministers  in  a  responsible  cab- 
inet system  must  have  the  confidence  of  Parliament  to  remain  in  office. 
Ours,  of  course,  is  not  a  responsible  cabinet  system,  nor  is  it  equipped  with 
the  parliamentary  procedures  for  expressing  confidence  or  lack  of  confi- 
dence. Nevertheless,  considerations  of  legislative  confidence  play  a  signifi- 
cant part  in  the  selection  and  continuance  in  office  of  personnel  at  the  top 
levels  of  the  departments. 

In  the  selection  of  agency  heads,  a  long  tradition  concedes  to  the  Presi- 
dent fairly  final  discretion  in  the  choice  of  the  members  of  his  Cabinet. 
Spectacular  instances  of  senatorial  refusal  to  assent  to  such  presidential 
appointments  merely  confirm  the  general  rule  of  presidential  finality.  Yet 
in  making  even  these  appointments,  the  President  must  be  mindful  of  the 
probable  attitudes  of  Congress  toward  prospective  appointees. 

Lower-Level  Appointments.  Legislative  influence  on  appointments  be- 
low the  level  of  the  Cabinet  is  on  the  whole  more  potent  and  more  per- 
suasive. The  interest  of  Senators  in  appointments  to  positions  in  the  "little 
cabinet"  and  to  top  positions  in  agencies  not  of  Cabinet  status  has  tradition- 
ally been  of  a  patronage  character.  The  desire  has  been  to  place  in  these 
positions  persons  who  have  rendered  service  to  the  party,  and  the  actions  of 
Presidents  are  ordinarily  colored  by  the  same  inclinations.  Hence,  the 
usual  problem  of  reconciling  senatorial  and  presidential  preferences  has 
been  simply  that  of  allocating  positions  among  the  various  factions  of  the 
party  in  a  manner  to  provoke  the  minimum  dissatisfaction. 

When  tension  over  issues  is  high,  however,  senatorial  influence  may  be 
exerted  to  prevent  the  appointment  of  candidates  with  policy  views  con- 
trary to  those  held  by  the  dominant  coalition  in  the  Senate.  Thus,  in  1945, 
the  nomination  of  Aubrey  Williams — previously  an  officer  of  the  Works 
Progress  Administration,  former  administrator  of  the  National  Youth  Ad- 
ministration, subsequently  an  employee  of  the  National  Farmers  Union,  and 
regarded  by  many  as  considerably  left  of  center — to  be  Rural  Electrification 
Administrator  precipitated  a  heated  senatorial  debate.  His  competence  for 
the  job  was  certainly  as  adequate  as  that  of  most  candidates  ordinarily  nomi- 


356  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

nated  to  fill  such  offices.  The  debate  was  rather  on  the  policy  issues  implicit 
in  the  appointment  of  one  of  his  views.  That  such  debates  occur  so  rarely 
is  an  indication  of  the  effectiveness  of  senatorial  influence  in  screening  out 
possibilities  unacceptable  to  the  Senate  prior  to  nomination. 

Occasionally,  control  of  the  top  personnel  is  achieved  in  effect  by  deci- 
sions that  deprive  particular  individuals  of  control  over  particular  functions. 
Thus,  in  1945  when  the  President  nominated  Henry  Wallace  to  be  Secre- 
tary of  Commerce,  a  measure  was  initiated  in  the  Senate  to  remove  the 
Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation  and  its  subsidiaries  from  the  Depart- 
ment of  Commerce.  The  southern  right  wing  of  the  Democratic  Party  in 
coalition  with  the  Republicans  succeeded  in  preventing  direction  of  these 
important  corporations  by  Mr.  Wallace.  Although  cleavages  within  the 
Democratic  Party  were  the  dominant  factor  in  this  situation,  the  event 
was  not  without  its  instructive  aspects  on  congressional-executive  relations 
generally.  Senator  George,  the  sponsor  of  the  bill  of  divorcement,  stated: 

...  I  think  the  vast  powers  and  vast  authority  given  [to  the  Recon- 
struction Finance  Corporation]  is  the  strongest  possible  argument  that 
anyone  can  make  for  the  return,  or  for  the  hastening  of  the  return,  of 
these  powers  to  an  independent  agency  of  the  Government  created  by 
the  Congress  and  responsible  to  the  Congress. . . . 

I  am  firmly  of  the  opinion,  myself,  that  as  we  follow  through  the 
mobilization  period  to  the  end  of  the  war,  whenever  it  may  come,  and 
as  we  also  enter  into  and  follow  through  the  reconversion  period,  that 
this  direct  responsibility  ought  to  be  recognized  by  the  Congress  and 
ought  not  to  be  placed,  or  continued,  in  an  officer  in  the  executive  branch 
of  the  Government  who  is  a  part  of  the  official  family,  so  to  speak,  of  the 
Chief  Executive  of  the  Nation.16 

Attempted  Extension  of  Senatorial  Confirmation.  Control  by  Senators 
and  Representatives  of  appointments  further  down  the  administrative 
hierarchy  has  differed  from  time  to  time  with  the  waxing  and  waning  of 
the  spoils  system.  Our  traditions  have  accorded  great  influence  to  Senators 
and  Representatives  in  appointments  to  the  public  service.  During  this  cen- 
tury, however,  with  the  strengthening  of  the  merit  system,  large  blocks  of 
employees  have  been  removed  from  the  realm  of  congressional  patronage.17 

Apart  from  informal  "clearance"  of  appointments  with  Representatives 
and  Senators,  Congress  on  occasion  attempts  to  broaden  its  formal  control 
by  the  extension  of  senatorial  confirmation  to  large  numbers  of  lower  posi- 
tions. Thus,  under  various  work  relief  appropriation  acts  from  1935  to  1942, 
senatorial  confirmation  was  required  for  federal  appointments  as  state  and 
regional  administrators  receiving  more  than  $5,000  annually.  Scattered  statu- 
tory provisions  of  similar  purport  were  placed  in  various  war  agency  appro- 

16  Senate  Committee  on  Commerce,  Hearings  on  S.  375,  p.  10,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.. 
January  24  and  25,  1945. 

17  See  the  excellent  study  by  Fowler,  Dorothy  Ganficld,  "Congressional  Dictation  of  Local 
Appointments,"  Journal  of  Politics,  1945,  Vol.  7,  pp.  25-57. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  357 

priation  acts.  One  act  applying  to  the  War  Manpower  Commission  stipu- 
lated, for  example,  that  no  one  might  be  appointed  at  a  salary  of  over  $4,500 
save  by  the  President  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  the  Senate.  The  actual 
administrative  consequences  of  the  requirement  of  confirmation  have  never 
been  carefully  analyzed.  Certainly  in  some  situations  the  result  is  that  a 
Senator  may  have  at  least  a  veto  over  important  administrative  actions 
within  his  state. 

The  debate  in  1943  over  a  proposal  to  extend  the  confirmation  require- 
ment to  all  employees  receiving  in  excess  of  $4,500  a  year  illuminates  the 
theoretical  problems  of  administration  involved  in  legislative  control  of 
appointments.  Some  Senators  indicated  a  desire  to  prevent  abuses  such  as 
the  payment  of  excessive  salaries  to  unqualified  individuals.  Others  thought 
that  by  having  a  hand  in  the  selection  of  subordinate  personnel,  the  Senate 
might  gain  a  greater  voice  in  the  policies  of  administrative  agencies.  Sen- 
ator Vandenburg  asserted  that  "this  is  one  of  the  few  ways  in  which  Con- 
gress can  reach  back  into  the  implementing  of  its  delegated  powers,  and 
have  something  to  say  and  do  by  way  of  limitation  of  the  sprawling 
bureaucracy  which  is  the  curse  of  our  present-day  democracy."  On  the 
other  hand,  the  President  asserted  that  the  bill  "presupposes  congressional 
responsibility  for  the  operations  of  executive  agencies."  If  the  power  of 
appointment  of  subordinate  personnel  were  divided  between  the  Senate  and 
department  heads,  he  saw  a  dissipation  of  responsibility  for  the  success  of 
an  agency's  program.18 

Removal  Power.  Control  of  personnel  includes  the  power  to  remove  as 
well  as  to  influence  selection.  Congress  has  no  ready  and  easy  method  by 
which  it  can  remove  officials  whose  attitudes  or  policies  are  not  to  its  liking. 
The  power  of  impeachment  is  a  blunderbuss  of  no  utility.  The  power  to 
specify  that  no  funds  shall  be  available  for  the  employment  of  particular 
individuals  has  been  used  in  scattered  instances  against  relatively  unimpor- 
tant employees  of  the  executive  branch.  But  there  is  no  clean-cut  method 
by  which  the  legislature  can  simply  say,  "We  have  nothing  against  you  per- 
sonally. Nor  do  we  question  your  competence  or  your  Americanism.  Our 
views  on  what  the  policy  of  your  department  should  be  are  not  the  same 
as  yours.  You  are  fired."  The  lack  of  workable  means  for  the  removal  by 
Congress  of  executive  officers  is,  of  course,  merely  the  corollary  of  independ- 
ence of  the  chief  executive— the  glory  or  the  fatal  defect  of  the  American 
system  of  government,  depending  on  the  point  of  view. 

Nevertheless,  a  determined  legislature  can  virtually  drive  a  man  from 
office,  although  not  without  considerable  vituperation  and  recrimination. 
Exposure  of  corruption  and  the  consequent  forced  resignation  of  an  execu. 
tive  officer  occasionally  occur.  Resignations  on  account  of  incompatibility 
either  of  personality  or  policy  between  Congress  and  an  individual  officer 

18  Sec  the  analysis  by  Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  "Senatorial  Confirmation,"  Public  Adminis- 
tration Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  pp.  281-296. 


358  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

are  better  indications  of  the  fundamental  legislative  as  well  as  executive 
tendency  to  seek  relationships  of  confidence.  Occasionally  congressional  in- 
vestigations appear  to  have  as  their  primary  objective  the  removal  of  an 
executive  officer.  That  is,  the  investigation  is  certainly  not  designed  to  de- 
velop legislation;  nor  is  it  motivated  by  a  search  for  corruption.  It  aims 
to  oust  an  individual  whose  views  arouse  the  animosity  of  the  legislators 
spearheading  the  investigation. 

Legislative  Pressure  for  Resignation.  By  its  control  over  appropriations 
the  lawmaking  body  can  make  an  official  quite  uncomfortable.  In  some 
instances  arbitrary  cuts  in  budget  estimates  are  made  because  of  congres- 
sional dislike  of  an  individual,  disagreement  with  his  policies,  or  other  re- 
lated reasons.  The  pressure  is  thus  on  him  to  resign  lest  by  continuance 
in  office  he  will  damage  the  agency  which  he  heads  or  serves.  In  other 
cases,  by  persistent  criticism  from  the  floor,  by  frequent  adoption  of  limit- 
ing legislation,  and  by  similar  means  an  official  may  be  thoroughly  persuaded 
that  his  period  of  usefulness  is  ended.  Congress  is  most  effective  in  its 
efforts  to  terminate  the  services  of  a  particular  individual  when  it  has  sup- 
port in  the  press  and  the  public  generally.  A  common  pattern  of  behavior 
is  that  the  executive  branch  attempts  to  weather  the  congressional  storm. 
Then,  perhaps  in  the  wake  of  a  "moral"  victory,  a  resignation  occurs  after 
things  have  quieted  down.  The  formality  of  executive  independence  is 
preserved  but  the  actuality  of  legislative  discharge  prevails.19 

No  matter  who  is  President  or  what  the  conditions  of  the  time  are, 
Congress  exerts  influence  over  the  selection  of  the  principal  administrative 
officers.  Harmonious  relations  between  the  chief  executive  and  the  legisla- 
ture do  not  indicate  the  absence  of  congressional  participation  in  appoint- 
ments. This  general  condition  may  only  reflect  careful  consideration  of  con- 
gressional wishes.  Legislative  attitudes  become  more  apparent  when  differ- 
ences of  policy  exist  between  the  President  and  Congress.  During  Democratic 
administrations  the  conservative  wing  of  the  party  usually  is  in  a  position 
to  make  its  divergent  views  strongly  felt  because  of  its  strength  in  the  Sen- 
ate. Similarly,  during  Republication  administrations  the  western  liberal  wing 
of  the  party  makes  itself  felt  because  of  a  like  advantageous  position  in  the 
same  body. 

5.  DRIVES  TOWARD  REFORM 

Of  prescriptions  to  cure  the  ills  of  Congress  there  is  no  dearth.  Hopeful 
souls  come  forward  at  moments  when  they  can  gain  a  hearing  and  attempt 
to  market  their  cures  for  Congress.  A  massive  sales  resistance  usually  meets 
their  offerings,  which  are  often  based  on  faulty  diagnoses.  The  principal 
error  in  diagnosis  made  by  reformers  is  that  they  approach  Congress  in  iso- 
lation from  the  rest  of  the  government.  The  basic  issues  involve  the  struc- 

19  See  the  penetrating  case  study  by  Leigh,  Robert  D.,  "Politicians  vs.  Bureaucrats,"  Harper's 
Magazine,  Vol.  190,  January,  1945,  pp.  97-105. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  359 

ture  of  the  entire  government  rather  than  Congress  alone.  They  are  almost 
invariably  associated  with  the  fundamental  principle  of  separation  of 
powers. 

Case  for  Cabinet  Government.  Outright  adoption  of  the  principle  of 
cabinet  responsibility  has  been  strongly  urged  by  a  few  students  of  gov- 
ernment,20 but  sentiment  in  support  of  such  a  move  is  not  nearly  so  strong 
as  it  once  was.  The  British  system  in  its  current  usages  has  come  to  be 
recognized  as  something  radically  different  from  the  older  conceptions  of 
that  system.  Furthermore,  the  manner  in  which  it  would  operate  under 
American  conditions  is  quite  unpredictable.21 

The  transplantation  of  the  cabinet  system  would  deprive  us  of  the 
strength  that  inheres  in  the  presidency,  and  might  produce  the  instability  as- 
sociated with  the  French  parliamentary  system  rather  than  arrangements 
sifiilar  to  those  of  Great  Britain  and  the  Dominions.  Moreover,  it  would 
necessitate  a  drastic  revision  of  the  working  relationships  between  our  two 
legislative  chambers  and  the  consequent  decline  of  the  strength  accorded  in 
our  federal  system  to  the  states  with  small  populations.  Whatever  our  prog- 
nosis of  the  results  of  adopting  the  cabinet  system  may  be,  the  likelihood  of 
such  action  is  remote.  We  must  work  out  our  constitutional  problems 
within  the  framework  of  the  system  of  separation  of  powers.  As  a  measure 
of  conservative  experimentation,  we  can  only  suggest  that  it  might  be 
worthwhile  to  try  out  the  cabinet  arrangement  in  one  or  two  states  to  see 
how  it  would  operate  under  American  conditions. 

The  drive  for  congressional  reform  has  its  peaks  and  its  valleys.  The 
policies  of  the  Roosevelt  administrations  in  depression  and  war  stimulated  un- 
usual agitation  among  both  members  of  Congress  and  citizens  for  a  thorough- 
going reconsideration  of  the  function  anc1  role  of  Congress.  With  proposals 
for  the  purely  internal  reorganization  of  the  legislative  process,  we  have  no 
concern  here.  However,  the  various  suggestions  for  alteration  of  the  rela- 
tionships between  the  legislative  and  executive  branches  are  of  interest  in 
throwing  light  on  the  general  problem  dealt  with  in  this  chapter. 

Merits  of  a  Question  Period.  Representative  Estes  Kefauver  of  Tennessee 
attracted  considerable  attention  by  his  proposal  to  introduce  a  "question 
period,"  modeled  on  British  practice,  when  heads  of  executive  agencies 
would  appear  before  the  House  of  Representatives  to  reply  to  questions  of 
which  they  had  received  advance  notice.22  Such  an  arrangement  would 
permit  members  of  the  Cabinet  and  the  heads  of  other  agencies  to  answer 
criticisms  and  explain  policies.  Appearance  of  executive  officers  before  the 
entire  House  would  limit  the  monopoly  of  information  which  committees 

20  See,  for  example,  the  persuasive  study  by  Hazlitt,  Henry,  A  New  Constitution  Now, 
New  York:  Whittlesey,  1942. 

21  For  critical  observations,  see  Price,  Don  K.,  "The  Parliamentary  and  Presidential  Systems," 
Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  pp.  317-334. 

^  Sec  Kefauver,  Estes,  "The  Need  for  Better  Executive-Legislative  Teamwork  in  the 
National  Government,"  American  Political  Snencr  Rrpteu',  1944,  Vol.  38,  pp.  317-325. 


360  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

tend  to  have  of  subjects  within  their  jurisdiction.  This  might  somewhat 
weaken  the  committees.  It  is  not  without  significance  that  many  of  the 
"older  heads"  within  the  House — those  who  hold  committee  chairmanships 
and  other  positions  of  leadership — were  strongly  opposed  to  the  Kefauver 
proposal.  Conversely,  the  chief  proponents  of  such  measures  tend  to  be 
newer  members  of  Congress  who  have  little  opportunity  to  utilize  their 
talents  because  of  their  lack  of  seniority. 

Legislative  Committee  Meetings  with  Administrators.  A  variety  of 
other  schemes  are  suggested  from  time  to  time  to  produce  a  closer  liaison 
between  Congress  and  the  administrative  departments.  Thus,  it  is  proposed 
that  individual  legislators  meet  at  frequent  intervals  with  their  opposite 
numbers  in  the  executive  branch  to  consider  forthcoming  problems,  to  in- 
form Congress,  and  to  bring  the  views  of  Congress  to  the  executive  officer 
concerned.  This  kind  of  arrangement  is  occasionally  formalized  for  a  tirfe 
by  particular  committees. 

While  closer  relationships  between  executive  officials  and  legislative  com- 
mittees are  in  some  ways  advantageous,  they  also  may  contribute  to  the  dis- 
integration of  administration.  Congressional  committees  tend  to  be  en- 
thusiasts for  the  matters  with  which  they  deal.  The  public  interest  is  not 
necessarily  better  promoted  by  giving,  for  example,  the  committees  on  agri- 
culture in  either  chamber  a  stronger  voice  in  the  management  of  the 
Department  of  Agriculture  than  they  now  have. 

Legislative  Staffs.  Better  staffing  of  Congress  is  another  favorite  attack 
on  the  problem.23  This  is  to  serve  two  purposes:  to  aid  the  legislator  in 
handling  his  legislative  business;  and  to  aid  him  in  handling  his  constitu- 
ents' business.  A  more  or  less  professionalized  class  of  congressional  secreta- 
ries has  been  developed  consisting  of  men  and  women  who  "know"  Wash- 
ington and  who  run  the  errands  that  inevitably  are  the  lot  of  legislators, 
not  always  unsolicited.  More  significant  issues  are  raised  by  the  need  for 
assistance  to  the  legislator  in  his  legislative  business. 

In  the  staffing  of  congressional  committees  it  is  sometimes  assumed  that 
by  this  means  the  legislature  can  do  directly  many  things  which  the  execu- 
tive branch  should  do.  We  can  make  ourselves  felt — so  the  speculation  runs 
— if  we  have  staff  to  help  us  dig  into  the  bureaucracies.  When  intelligently 
used,  expert  staff  can  make  Congress  much  more  effective.  However,  by 
overstaffing  Congress  we  run  the  danger  of  merely  setting  up  another 
bureaucracy  "on  the  Hill"  to  do  a  job  which,  if  it  is  not  already  being  done 
elsewhere,  ought  to  be.  The  contribution  of  the  lawmaker  in  the  govern- 
mental process  is  not  in  the  exercise  of  professional  expertness.  If  he  merely 
mouths  what  his  experts  tell  him,  we  lose  important  values  of  representative 
government. 


23  Sec,  for  example,  Heller,  Robert,  Strengthening  the  Congress,  Washington:  National 
Planning  Association,  1944;  Hamilton,  Walton,  "Blueprint  for  a  Virile  Congress,"  New  York 
Times  Magazine,  September  10,  1944. 


LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL  361 

X 

Making  Legislative  Wort^  Manageable.  These  remarks  suggest  that  one 
of  the  most  important  currents  of  reform  is  that  of  drawing  the  line  between 
what  the  legislative  body  ought  to  do  and  what  it  ought  to  demand  that  the 
executive  branch  do  well.  No  matter  how  much  staff  it  builds  up,  Con- 
gress cannot  make  all  the  decisions  of  government  unless  we  change  radi- 
cally the  nature  of  our  system.  To  make  its  job  manageable,  Congress 
needs  to  slough  off  a  mass  of  minutiae  which  now  absorbs  its  time  and 
energies.  One  means  by  which  it  might  shift  a  great  volume  of  work  to  the 
executive  branch  would  be  through  adoption  of  the  British  provisional 
order  system — that  is,  rules  and  regulations  made  by  the  executive  agencies 
would  become  effective  within  a  specified  time  unless  Congress  decided  to 
the  contrary. 

The  most  notable  example  of  the  use  of  this  technique  in  the  United 
States  was  under  the  Reorganization  Acts  of  1939  and  1945,  which  empow- 
ered the  President  to  submit  so-called  reorganization  plans  to  become  ef- 
fective unless  disapproved  by  concurrent  resolution.  Over  many  subjects, 
this  arrangement  would  actually  reserve  for  Congress  more  substantial  control 
than  it  now  possesses,  especially  under  legislation  empowering  an  agency  to 
regulate  an  industry  in  "the  public  interest."  In  the  exercise  of  such  powers, 
executive  officers  would  also  often  be  much  more  comfortable  if  their  actions 
were  subject  to  general  congressional  review.  The  endless  criticism  for  ex- 
ceeding legislative  grants  of  power  might  be  effectively  terminated,  and 
policy  questions  which  probably  ought  to  have  congressional  approval  would 
not  be  settled  finally  by  the  executive  branch,  as  they  now  are. 

A  recent  proposal  has  been  aimed  at  the  establishment  of  a  Joint  Execu- 
tive-Legislative Cabinet.  It  would  consist  of  perhaps  nine  congressional 
leaders  and  nine  members  of  the  executive  Cabinet.  It  would  be  presided 
over  by  the  President.  This  arrangement  would  undertake  to  maintain 
agreement  on  the  principal  lines  of  policy  and  legislation.  In  the  event  of 
a  deadlock  between  himself  and  Congress,  the  President  could  dissolve  the 
legislature  and  order  a  new  election.24 

Many  variations  of  the  foregoing  proposals  have  been  made,25  and  the 
entire  range  of  possibilities  was  explored  by  a  joint  committee  set  up  by 
Congress  late  in  1944.20  There  are  those  who  believe  that  adoption  of  one 
or  more  of  these  schemes  would  ensure  peace  and  harmony  in  executive- 


2* See  Finlettcr,  Thomas  K.,  Can  Representative  Government  Do  the  Job?,  New  York: 
Reynal  &  Hitchcock,  1945. 

25  See  the  useful  survey  in  The  Reorganization  of  Congress,  A  Report  of  the  Committee 
on  Congress  of  the  American  Political  Science  Association,  Washington:   Public  Affairs  Press, 
1945. 

26  See  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Congress,  First  Progress  Report,  Sen.  Doc. 
No.  36,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.   The  hearings  before  the  joint  committee  constitute  a  valuable 
source  of  information  about  the  workings  of  Congress;  Hearings  before  the  Joint  Committee  on 
the  Organization  of  Congress  pursuant  to  H.  Con.  Res.  No.  18,  1945,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess. 
The  committee's  final  report  appeared  as  House  Report  No.  1675,  79th  Cong.,  2d  Sess..  March 
4,  1946. 


362  LEGISLATIVE  CONTROL 

legislative  relationships.  That  celestial  state  of  affairs  will  probably  never 
come  about  because  executive-legislative  differences  often  boil  down  to  the 
issue  of  who  will  rule.  That  issue  cannot  be  settled  without  doing  violence 
to  the  theory  of  separation  of  powers,  which  presupposes  that  Congress 
and  the  President  share  the  power  to  rule.  Friction  is  inevitable  and,  we 
might  add,  probably  desirable  within  proper  bounds.  Nevertheless,  much 
senseless  controversy  could  be  eliminated  if  administrators  exerted  more 
persistent  and  more  intelligent  efforts  to  keep  legislators  informed  of  the 
affairs  of  state  and,  in  turn,  to  inform  themselves  of  the  views  of  legislators. 


Part  III 
WORKING  METHODS 


CHAPTER 


The  Formulation  of  Administrative  Policy 

1.   POLICY  FORMATION  AND  POLICY  SANCTION 

Realm  of  Administrative  Policy.  The  primary  organ  of  policy  sanction 
is  the  legislature.  In  the  main,  it  lays  down  policy  in  general  terms.  For 
purposes  of  effective  government  such  general  policy,  usually  expressed  in 
statutes,  must  be  made  more  specific.  This  is  done  by  administrative  policy- 
formulation  as  an  implementation  of  statutory  directions  addressed  to  the 
executive  branch. 

Policy  in  the  latter  sense  may  consist  of  the  determination  of  a  long-range 
work  program,  such  as  the  number  of  applications  to  be  processed,  surplus 
items  to  be  sold,  inspections  to  be  made,  projects  to  be  completed,  during 
a  given  time  period.  It  may  mean  establishing  a  criterion  or  standard  for 
the  guidance  of  staff  thinking  in  making  decisions  on  recurrent  matters 
in  the  course  of  day-to-day  operations.  Or  it  may  mean  a  highly  specific 
decision — for  instance,  whether  a  precedent-setting  letter  should  be  sent  out 
or  an  important  appointment  made.  In  the  broadest  sense,  however,  a  pol- 
icy question  is  one  which  requires  an  authoritative  determination  as  to 
whether  or  not  a  new  program  or  change  in  an  existing  plan  of  action 
should  be  undertaken. 

Breadth  of  Policy-Making  Process.  Formal  determination — or  final  ap- 
proval— of  a  proposal  setting  forth  what  should  be  done  occupies  a  very 
small  segment  of  time  in  the  process  of  policy  making.  This  is  true  es- 
pecially in  the  case  of  administrative  operations,  unless  the  top  administrator 
undertakes  personally  to  review  the  basis  of  all  decisions  he  is  called  upon 
to  make,  which  would  create  an  impossible  bottleneck  at  his  desk.  On  the 
other  hand,  one  mark  of  a  good  executive  is  his  ability  to  decide  quickly 
whether  more  staff  work  or  more  thorough  planning  needs  to  be  done  be- 
fore he  can  intelligently  consider  a  proposed  action.  Policy  questions  that 
raise  issues  about  his  basic  program  objectives  or  the  kind  of  structural 
arrangements  and  administrative  coordination  he  wants  in  his  organization 

365 


366  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

will  require  more  of  his  time  than  operating  decisions,  the  bulk  of  which 
he  must  delegate  to  his  immediate  line  subordinates. 

On  either  type  of  policy  question,  however,  regardless  of  the  time  ele- 
ment involved,  the  final  formal  decision  is  preceded  by  an  evolutionary 
stage  of  formulation.  This  begins  with  the  spotting  of  some  concrete  needs 
and  identification  of  the  problem,  leading  to  investigation  and  analysis. 
It  is  carried  forward  to  the  point  of  corrective  recommendations,  leading 
in  turn  to  formal  initiation  of  the  proposed  action  for  review  and  approval 
or  rejection  in  terms  of  its  implications  for  existing  practices  and  relation- 
ships. Ultimate  determination  is  succeeded  by  the  stage  of  execution, 
which  consists  of  a  decignation  of  the  individual  responsible  and  the  proce- 
dures to  be  followed  for  applying  the  controlling  policy  or  general  plan  of 
action  in  particular  cases. 

Prompting  Role  of  Management.  Once  the  main  lines  of  program  ob- 
jective, structural  grouping,  and  functional  coordination  have  been  laid  down, 
neither  formulation  nor  execution  of  policy  as  a  matter  of  practice  is  sharply 
distinct  from  the  other.  Policy  issues  are  continually  arising  out  of 
problems  of  execution,  and  solutions  may  be  initiated  at  any  phase  of  exe- 
cution. New  facts,  different  situations,  and  changing  pressures  are  con- 
stantly coming  up  which  necessitate  decisions  by  operating  officials  or  else 
require  requests  for  policy  clearance  or  approval  of  proposed  action  on  a 
higher  level.1  A  well-managed  agency  properly  encourages  such  suggestions 
from  below.  However,  they  must  be  analyzed  and  reviewed  in  the  wider 
policy  perspective  to  determine  whether  the  proposed  measure  falls  within 
existing  policy  or  whether  the  policy  itself  should  be  modified. 

One  task  of  management,  therefore,  is  to  establish  appropriate  methods 
for  identifying  existing  or  potential  problems,  and  to  provide  channels  for 
sifting  and  expediting  consideration  of  policy  issues  at  the  most  suitable 
agency  levels.2  The  determination  having  been  made,  it  is  equally  important 
that  its  substance  and  its  rationale  be  quickly  disseminated  to  the  whole  staff 
and  to  the  public  affected  by  it.  The  ease  and  effectiveness  with  which  an 
agency  educates  itself  and  its  public  as  to  its  own  policies  and  any  changes 
in  them,  determines  in  large  measure  its  ability  to  dispose  of  its  work  with 
ease  and  effectiveness  at  operating  levels. 

Legislative  Basis  of  Administrative  Policy.  On  a  broader  scale,  the  same 

1  As  stated  by  Laves,  Walter  H.  C.  and  Wilcox,  Francis  O.,  "Organizing  the  Government 
for  Participation  in  World  Affairs,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  927: 
"Foreign  policies  like  other  policies  are  not  made  at  the  top.  They  are  an  institutional  product 
rather  than  orders  issued  from  above.  They  are  submitted  in  a  hundred  different  ways  through 
staff  decisions  and  recommendations,  to  be  tacitly  or  explicitly  approved  or  disapproved." 

2  "The  whole  process  is  one  of  varying  degrees  of  importance.  .  .  .  Organization  consists 
of  fixing  responsibility  for  decisions  at  those  points  where  there  is  appropriate  competence  to 
make   them   in   terms  of  experience   and   perspective."    Blandford,  John  B.,   "Coordinating 
Administration/'  p.  94,  Proceedings,  28th  Conference  of  the  Governmental  Research  Association, 
Detroit,   1940.    See  also  Applcby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  pp.  88-94,  120-124,  New  York: 
Knopf,  1945. 


THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  367 

process  that  goes  on  in  administrative  organizations  occurs  in  legislative 
policy-making,  except  that  most  of  the  issues  do  not  arise  out  of  daily  opera- 
tions of  the  legislature's  own  staff.  In  a  sense,  the  legislative  body  acts  as 
something  like  a  board  of  directors  for  all  administrative  agencies,  but  pol- 
icy determination  is  divided  between  it  and  another  political  organ,  the 
chief  executive.  Both,  separately  or  jointly,  determine  policy  that  is  binding 
upon  administrative  agencies. 

This  division  seems  to  assume  two  principal  channels  for  policy  formu- 
lation: one  from  the  people  through  their  elected  representatives;  the  other 
from  administrative  officials  to  the  chief  executive.  The  interaction  between 
these  two  processes  would  be  relatively  simple  if  the  legislature  confined 
its  role  in  policy  formulation  to  approving  or  disapproving  policy  proposals 
submitted  to  it  by  the  chief  executive,  whether  through  statutory  enactments 
or  through  the  positive  or  negative  exercise  of  its  power  to  appropriate 
the  funds  estimated  to  be  necessary  for  the  achievement  of  stated  public 
purposes.  English-speaking  countries,  however,  have  rejected  such  sim- 
plicity after  an  historic  struggle  for  control  of  the  royal  or  executive  pre- 
rogative. As  a  result,  the  legislature  established  its  constitutional  power 
not  only  to  decide  whether  money  should  be  spent  for  a  public  purpose, 
but  also  to  take  the  initiative  in  policy  making  and  extend  it  to  defining 
the  method,  principles,  and  organization  by  which  that  purpose  should  be 
attained. 

Main  Division  of  Responsibility.  Nevertheless,  the  scope  of  governmental 
functions  under  modern  industrial  and  technological  conditions  is  so  vast 
that  legislative  bodies  from  sheer  necessity  have  delegated  more  and  more 
responsibility  for  the  content  of  policy  proposals  to  administrative  agencies. 
In  these  agencies,  more  technically  competent,  comprehensive,  and  balanced 
consideration  of  the  issues  is  possible  than  in  the  atmosphere  and  procedures 
of  large  legislative  assemblies.  The  magnitude  and  pressure  of  public  busi- 
ness upon  legislatures  has  forced  them  to  relinquish  much  of  their  initiating 
and  planning  function  to  the  chief  executive,  thereby  enhancing  the  impor- 
tance of  legislative  review  and  approval  of  administrative  proposals.  Such 
legislative  review  and  approval  are  most  effectively  exercised  in  the  creation 
or  modification  of  administrative  powers,3  whereby  administrative  policy  is 
controlled  prospectively — in  the  first  instance  by  basic  legislative  authoriza- 
tion, in  the  second  by  appropriation  of  funds. 

The  distinction  between  legislative  and  administrative  policy  does  not 
turn  so  much  upon  an  inherent  difference  in  the  content  of  policy  as  upon 
the  extent  to  which  the  proposed  innovation  or  plan  of  action  involves  a 
fundamental  change  in  existing  public  policy.  The  new  program  or  policy 
will  require  legislative  authorisation  primarily  as  it  calls  for  amendment  or 
revision  of  established  practices  or  expectancies  around  which  public  feelings 

8  See  Jennings,  W.  Ivor,  Cabinet  Government,  pp.  177-178,  London:  Cambridge  Uni* 
versity  Press,  1937. 


368  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

or  economic  interests  have  become  consolidated.  No  satisfactory  substitute 
has  been  found  for  the  educational  value  of  public  discussion  created  by 
open  investigation  and  debate,  the  safeguards  implicit  in  public  hearings,  and 
the  stability  gained  by  survival  of  the  legislative  crucible  and  the  embodi- 
ment of  policy  in  the  form  of  law.  The  great  hazards  in  the  legislative 
process  are  the  distorting  influences  of  partisan  forces  seeking  narrow  ob- 
jectives through  piecemeal  amendment,  regardless — and  sometimes  at  the 
price — of  the  over-all  plan. 

Coordinate  Tas^s  of  Legislature  and  Chief  Executive.  It  is  often  claimed 
that  the  chief  executive  is  in  a  better  position  than  the  lawmaking  body  to 
secure  expert  consideration  of  policy  questions  in  the  light  of  the  complexi- 
ties and  conflicts  that  have  to  be  reconciled.  However,  he  has  his  own 
problems  of  maintaining  personal  relationships  with  the  leaders  of  his  party 
in  the  legislature,  appraising  the  popularity  of  policy  proposals  in  terms  of 
votes,  and  ensuring  cohesion  of  his  party  organization.  Given  the  multi- 
plicity of  policy  initiators  in  the  legislature,  it  is  clear  nevertheless  that  he 
has  an  important  and  legitimate  function  on  behalf  of  the  whole  people 
to  state  authoritatively  his  opinion  on  the  substance  of  proposed  policy.  He 
is  best  placed  to  answer  the  question  of  how  far  policy  should  be  formu- 
lated on  the  basis  of  considerations  deemed  important  by  the  experts  in 
getting  votes — the  politicians — and  how  much  weight  should  be  given  the 
factors  deemed  important  by  the  experts  in  getting  the  job  done — the 
administrators. 

Put  in  another  way,  our  constitutional  system  assumes  the  desirability 
of  divided  responsibility  and  rivalry  between  chief  executive  and  legislature. 
As  a  consequence,  the  chief  executive  bears  a  large  part  of  the  burden  of 
formulating  and  explaining  the  need  for  changed  public  policies  and  for 
focusing  the  legislators'  attention  upon  the  issues  which  they  should  decide, 
as  distinct  from  those  decisions  which  should  be  left  to  administrative 
judgment  and  competence,4 

2.  FACT-FINDING  AND  DISCRETION  IN  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

Delegation  of  Policy  Determination.  Much  discussion  and  analysis, 
particularly  in  legal  literature,  has  been  devoted  to  the  legislative  delegation 
of  rule-making  power  to  the  discretionary  judgment  of  administrative  offi- 
cials. No  analysis  of  the  technical  legal  arguments  need  be  made  here  be- 
cause we  shall  examine  them  in  a  later  chapter.  The  present  discussion  starts 
from  the  basic  premise  that  a  legislative  body  cannot  administer.  The  prac- 
tical question,  therefore,  is  the  extent  to  which  it  is  desirable  for  the  statute 

4  Cf.  Goodnow,  Frank  J.,  Politics  and  Administration,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1900; 
Schumpeter,  Joseph  A.,  Capitalism,  Socialism  and  Democracy,  pp.  269-302,  New  York: 
Harper,  1942;  Watkins,  Frederick  W.,  "Constitutional  Dictatorship,"  in  Friedrich,  Carl  J.  and 
Mason,  Edward  S.,  eds.,  Public  Policy,  p.  324  ff.9  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1940; 
Lindsay,  A.  D.,  The  Modem  Democratic  State,  pp.  143-146,  London:  Oxford  University  Press, 
1943;  Jordan,  Elijah,  The  Theory  of  Legislation,  Indianapolis:  Progress  Publishing  Co.,  1930. 


THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  369 

to  prescribe  in  detail  the  methods  of  achieving  its  purpose.  In  other  words, 
how  free  a  choice  of  means  should  be  given  the  administrator? 

The  legal  question  of  delegation  really  goes  to  the  problem  of  the  desir- 
ability of  the  general  policy.  The  Supreme  Court  has  made  it  clear  that  if 
the  legislature  has  the  authority  to  adopt  a  given  program  of  action  or  plan 
of  regulation,  it  may  prescribe  the  method  of  achieving  that  program  in 
either  general  or  specific  terms.  In  doing  so,  it  is  subject  to  only  two  major 
conditions:  first,  responsibility  for  achieving  the  public  purpose  or  program 
should  be  vested  in  public  officials;  second,  the  statutory  statement  of  the 
public  purpose  should  be  expressed  in  terms  that  are  sufficiently  clear  to 
afford  a  criterion  by  which  the  courts  may  judge  whether  the  administrative 
policy  has  a  reasonable  relationship  to  the  basic  statutory  purpose.5  Assum- 
ing the  constitutionality  of  the  legislative  purpose,  the  problem  of  adminis- 
trative policy-makers  is  to  determine  whether  the  conditions  exist  under 
which  the  adopted  policy  should  be  applied  and  what  should  be  done  to 
give  it  effect.  In  these  terms,  the  proper  criterion  for  appraising  administra- 
tive discretion  is  the  reliability  and  accuracy  of  the  information  upon  which 
such  determinations  are  based. 

Congress,  the  statute  itself,  and  functional  groups  exert  pressures  which 
in  their  combined  effects  upon  administrators  tend  to  force  them  to  seek  as 
complete  a  finding  of  the  facts,  as  rigorous  an  analysis  of  the  relevant  issues, 
and  as  precise  a  statement  of  the  assumptions  and  reasoning  upon  which 
the  administrative  approach  should  be  based,  as  can  be  obtained  from  their 
staffs.  In  this  view,  which  holds  that  as  a  rule  the  top  official  of  an  agency 
is  intent  upon  performing  his  tasks  as  fairly  and  effectively  as  he  knows 
how,  the  principal  limitation  upon  the  quality  of  administrative  policy  is 
the  scope  and  reliability  of  the  facilities  for  analyzing  and  presenting  in- 
formation to  him.  He  must  rely  in  large  measure  upon  the  statement  of 
the  issues  that  his  staff  presents  to  him.  The  question,  therefore,  is  how  the 
administrator  can  guard  himself  against  the  pitfalls  of  subjective  preferences, 
based  upon  superficial  or  narrow  assumptions  as  to  what  information  is 
relevant  and  what  issues  are  important. 

Administrative  Contacts  with  Private  Fact-Finding  Groups.  One  thing 
the  administrator  may  do  is  encourage  the  establishment  of  contacts  with 
private  fact-finding  groups  outside  of  government.  Outstanding  examples  of 
these  linkages  are  the  informal  relationships  between  the  Bureau  of  Agri- 
cultural Economics  and  the  farmer  organizations;  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Sta- 
tistics and  the  labor  organizations;  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 
and  the  Bureau  of  Railway  Economics  of  the  Association  of  American 
Railroads;  the  Office  of  Education  and  the  National  Education  Associa- 


te/. U.  S.  v.  Rock  Royal  Coop,  307  U.  S.  533  (1939);  Opp  Cotton  Mills  v.  Wage  and 
Hour  Administrator,  312  U.  S.  126  (1941);  Yakus  v.  United  States,  321  U.  S.  414  (1944); 
Corwin,  Edward  S.,  The  President:  Office  and  Powers,  pp.  111-126,  365-369,  New  York: 
New  York  University  Press,  1940.  C/.  also  below  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 


370  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

tion;  the  Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce  and  industry  trade 
associations;  the  Census  Bureau  and  the  American  Statistical  Association; 
the  Bureau  of  the  Budget  and  the  Public  Administration  Clearing  House 
and  its  affiliated  organizations  of  public  officials;  the  Children's  Bureau  and 
the  local  councils  of  private  welfare  agencies;  the  United  States  Public 
Health  Service  and  the  American  Medical  Association. 

Collaborative  relationships  in  planning  and  stimulating  research  pro- 
grams are  unquestionably  helpful  to  both  private  and  public  agencies,  some- 
times developing  into  well-understood  divisions  of  labor.  The  mutual  inter- 
est of  these  different  bodies  in  the  problems  of  the  same  economic  grouping 
in  the  population  or  the  same  area  of  professional  concern  arises  out  of 
essentially  similar  general  views  of  public  policy.  Administrative  policy 
should  therefore  be  on  its  guard  lest  the  factors  of  propinquity  bring  about 
a  public  distrust  of  the  reliability  of  the  agency's  official  judgments,  decisions, 
or  publications. 

Interagency  Use  of  Staff  Resources.  A  second  way  of  improving  staff 
sources  of  information  is  to  further  the  formation  of  technical  relations  and 
associations  with  officials  of  other  agencies  engaged  in  the  same  type  of 
work.  In  the  federal  government  the  Council  on  Personnel  Administration 
holds  monthly  meetings  of  departmental  personnel  officers.  Another  illus- 
tration is  the  Division  of  Statistical  Standards  in  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget. 
This  unit  performs  a  semiofficial  service  of  a  similar  character  for  agency 
statisticians  by  establishing  interagency  coordinating  committees  to  handle 
technical  problems  of  program  and  method.  Progress  and  results  of  the  plan- 
ning and  coordinating  activities  it  sponsors  are  described  in  a  monthly 
Statistical  Reporter? 

Arrangements  such  as  these  are  valuable.  They  widen  technical  points 
of  view.  They  increase  professional  experience  through  exchange  of  view- 
points and  information.  And  they  develop  support  for  interdepartmental 
programs  and  techniques  having  general  policy  significance  as  distinct  from 
purely  jurisdictional  bureau-centered  interest. 

Government-Wide  Clearance  of  Policy  Proposals.  A  third  way  of  placing 
an  agency  in  official  touch  with  external  sources  of  information  is  exempli- 
fied in  the  federal  government  by  the  procedure  of  formal  consultation  and 
clearance  of  legislative  matters  and  proposed  executive  orders  through  the 
Division  of  Legislative  Reference  in  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget.7  Any  recom- 
mendation for  legislative  enactment  or  report  by  an  agency  upon  pending 
legislation  must  be  put  before  the  bureau  before  submission  to  Congress. 
The  bureau  determines  what  other  agencies  are  affected  by  the  subject  mat- 
ter, supplies  them  with  a  copy  of  the  pertinent  materials,  and  requests  a 

6  Sec  also  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Two  Years  of  Progress  under  the  Federal  Reports  Act, 
Senate  Report  No.  47,  pt.  2,  79th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1945. 

?  See  Executive  Order  No.  8248  of  September  8,  1939;  Budget  Circular  A-19  (revised) 
of  August  1,  1944. 


THE  FORMuj-AijwjJN   <jF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  371 

statement  of  their  views  on  it.  Having  secured  the  views  of  all  agencies  con- 
cerned, the  bureau  ascertains  the  relationship  of  the  legislation  to  the  pro* 
gram  of  the  President,  and  communicates  its  finding  to  the  initiating  agency, 
which  in  its  report  to  Congress  must  include  a  statement  of  the  advice  re- 
ceived from  the  Budget  Bureau. 

This  channel,  of  course,  is  not  a  means  of  broadening  the  span  of  atten* 
tion  of  a  very  large  proportion  of  the  staff  of  a  department.  Formal  clear- 
ance procedure  represents  a  very  late  stage  in  the  interdepartmental  nego- 
tiation or  exchange  of  views.  "The  real  consideration  of  legislative  proposals 
in  administrative  circles  precedes,  rather  than  follows,  compliance  with  the 
formal  clearance  requirements/*8  Many  pieces  of  forward-looking  legislation 
in  recent  years  have  been  the  result  of  a  vast  measure  of  informal  prelimi- 
nary discussion  prior  to  the  initiation  of  final  proposals  through  formal 
channels.  Yet  the  existence  of  clearance  requirements  is  a  real  incentive 
to  interdepartmental  consultation. 

Ensuring  Objectivity  in  Staff  Recommendations.  Personal  and  profes- 
sional contacts  and  associations  across  departmental  lines  are  an  important 
means  of  broadening  staff  outlook  on  policy  questions.  Top  administrators 
also  have  a  strong  interest  in  establishing  devices  whereby  they  can  be 
assured  of  the  accuracy  of  the  facts  and  the  objectivity  of  statements  on 
the  issues  presented  to  them  for  decision.  This  problem  is  particularly  com- 
pelling when  the  administrator  acts  in  a  quasi-judicial  capacity,  in  which 
he  must  find  out  what  questions  really  are  at  issue  and  arrive  at  judgments 
as  to  what  should  be  done  on  the  facts  of  specific  cases.  Such  narrowing  of 
the  area  of  decision  in  specific  cases  from  general  arguments  to  definable 
factors  or  determinants  of  judgment  is  an  outstanding  feature  of  the  entire 
administrative  process.  It  accounts  for  much  of  the  emphasis  on  the  part 
of  regulatory  tribunals  and  agencies  upon  a  "fair  hearing,"  "decision  on  the 
record,"  and  "substantiality"  of  evidence. 

The  problem  is  not  restricted  to  quasi-judicial  processes  in  the  specific 
sense,  however.  Even  ordinary  administrative  orders  and  acts  must  be 
based  on  a  careful  scrutiny  of  all  the  relevant  facts.  Moreover,  all  rules  and 
regulations  prescribing  rights  or  obligations  of  individuals  must  be  drafted 
on  rigorously  analyzed  assumptions  as  to  the  type  of  situation  that  is  antici- 
pated or  planned  for.  Generalized  language  is  necessary,  but  trained 
analysis  in  advance  of  formal  promulgation  reduces  the  apparent  generality 
and  ensures  application  of  the  rules  within  concrete  and  often  quite  precise 
limits.9 

In  order  to  create  an  administrative  pattern  in  which  this  type  of  analy- 
sis operates  continuously  and  as  a  matter  of  course,  the  administrator  must 

8Witte,  Erwin  E.,  "Administrative  Agencies  and  Statute  Lawmaking,"  Public  Adminis- 
tration Review,  1942,  Vol.  2,  p.  119. 

°This  process  appears  to  conform  to  the  "utilitarian"  method  and  standard  of  arriving 
at  ethical  judgments,  which  has  been  applied  to  administrative  theory  by  Leys,  Wayne  A.  R., 
"Ethics  and  Administrative  Discretion,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  p.  10  ff. 


372  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

establish  machinery  for  institutional  planning  and  for  review  of  lower- 
level  decisions  or  recommendations.10  This  is  first  of  all  a  problem  of  key 
personnel,  which  rests  upon  a  relationship  of  personal  understanding  and 
cooperation  between  the  first  echelon  of  subordinates  and  the  top  adminis- 
trative authority,  whether  it  be  a  board  or  individual.  Once  the  personal 
relationships  at  the  top  have  been  established,  however,  administrative 
planning  is  properly  distinguishable  from  the  review  process. 

In  formulating  new  goals  of  administrative  effort,  planning  draws  upon 
all  facilities  and  personal  resources  in  the  organization,  regardless  of  lines  of 
responsibility.  The  function  of  review  is  closely  associated  with  existing 
lines  of  command,  and  with  the  responsibilities  of  supervisors  in  scrutiniz- 
ing the  quality  and  quantity  of  their  subordinates'  day-to-day  work.  In 
complex  organizations  like  the  Army  Service  Forces  and  the  War  Produc- 
tion Board  of  World  War  II,  the  two  functions  may  be  brought  together 
at  the  top  in  an  over-all  review  group— the  Control  Division  of  ASF  and 
the  Bureau  of  Planning  and  Statistics  of  WPB.  This  will  stimulate  self- 
analysis  and  improvement  in  performance  standards  as  well  as  reporting 
methods  on  the  part  of  operating  divisions.  Both  such  planning  and  review 
presuppose  thorough  fact-finding  as  a  basis  for  administrative  decision.11 
On  any  problem  of  policy  formulation,  they  rival  and  supplement  each  other 
by  emphasizing  different  facts  and  different  approaches  to  the  same  prob- 
lem for  attention  at  the  top.  Administrative  planning  should  be  closely 
tied  into  budget  formulation,  from  whose  planning  phases  it  is  indistin- 
guishable.12 

It  should  be  clear,  then,  that  the  administrative  approach  to  the  problem 
presented  by  legislative  delegation  of  discretion  to  achieve  a  broad  objective 
of  public  policy  does  not  assume  an  unfettered  choice  of  means.  For  ex- 
ample, the  annual  legislative  review  of  appropriation  requests  provides  a 
check.  The  technical  nature  of  the  particular  issues  imposes  certain  limita- 
tions. The  sources  of  information  and  devices  of  coordination  available  to 
top  executives  through  budgetary  and  management  channels,  functioning 
under  government-wide  standards,  establish  another  set  of  brakes.  The 
promotion  of  criteria  of  technical  competence  through  interagency  staff 
associations,  formal  and  informal,  are  further  important  controls  of  a  pro- 
fessional character.  Finally,  the  evolution  of  procedures  for  ensuring  ac- 
curate and  fair  determination  of  the  facts,  including  specific  recognition  of 
the  function  of  internal  administrative  planning  and  control,  represents  an 
advanced  form  of  research-in-action,  whose  principal  defect  is  the  narrow* 

10  Cf.   Simon,   Herbert  A.,   "Decision-Making  and  Administrative  Organization,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  26-29. 

11  In  the  words  of  Follett,  Mary  P.,  Dynamic  Administration,  p.  305,  New  York:  Harper, 
1942:  "I  have  given  four  principles  of  organization.  The  underpinning  of  these  is  information,. 
based  upon  research." 

&  Cf.  Walker,  Robert  A.,  "The  Relation  of  Budgeting  to  Program  Planning,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  97-107. 


THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  375 

considerations,  tend  to  dismiss  the  importance  of  technical  disagreements 
between  staff  on  problems  which  overlap  several  responsibilities  or  fall 
partially  outside  the  agency's  bailiwick.  In  short,  the  administrator  who 
encourages  initiative  creates  conflict  in  his  organization.  Under  these  con- 
ditions, to  him  the  paramount  desirability  often  appears  to  be  whatever 
policy  decision  offers  the  best  chance  of  enabling  the  organization  to  stick 
together — the  "good  of  the  service"  doctrine. 

Effects  of  Ideological  Orientation.  At  its  lowest  extreme,  the  need  for 
organizational  solidarity  may  stifle  all  initiative  apart  from  uniformity  with 
the  "party  line"  of  the  group  closest  to  the  agency  head.  In  its  higher  mani- 
festations, organizational  unity  encourages  objectivity  of  judgment  and  the 
raising  of  policy  questions  on  the  assurance  that  existing  policy  is  fully 
carried  out.  As  a  corollary,  this  solidarity  proscribes  special  favors  for  special 
groups  or  individuals  inside  and  outside  the  organization.  At  the  same 
time,  such  a  drive  for  unity  places  a  large  responsibility  for  policy  coordina- 
tion upon  the  agency  head  and  his  immediate  associates,  because  once  their 
authority  has  been  subdivided,  differences  over  policy  questions  among  them 
must  be  disposed  of  in  terms  of  the  prestige,  self-respect,  and  pride  of  every 
member  of  the  administrative  subdivisions  involved. 

Administrative  ideology,  therefore,  presents  a  very  complex  problem  in 
social  psychology.  Immediately  and  concretely,  administrative  policy  is 
to  a  large  degree  a  matter  of  personality  and  personal  relationships  between 
the  agency  head,  his  own  staff,  and  the  first  level  of  operating  subordinates. 
Ex  officio,  so  to  speak,  the  understandings  and  commitments  of  this  group 
determine  much  of  the  course  of  administrative  policy.  In  personnel 
changes  at  these  levels  may  be  sought  the  significant  clues  to  shifts  in  the 
direction  of  policy.  However,  the  ability  of  top  management  to  do  its  job 
in  achieving  the  purpose  of  the  organization  as  a  whole  depends  in  turn 
on  the  sense  of  contribution,  accomplishment,  and  participation  on  the  part 
of  the  working  groups  all  the  way  down  the  hierarchy.  In  the  face  of  the 
explosive  problems  generated  by  social  idealism,  personal  will-to-power, 
and  simple  demands  for  a  sense  of  job  satisfaction  by  men  working  in 
groups,  it  is  not  surprising  that  outsiders  get  the  impression  of  powerful, 
anonymous  influences  which  are  feared  because  they  are  not  understood. 

4.  EXTERNAL  INFLUENCES  AND  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

Impact  of  Interest  Groups.  Legislative  relationships  are,  of  course,  not 
the  only  external  influences  which  administrative  policy-making  must  take 
into  account.  Organized  pressure  groups  are  well  aware  of— and  some- 
times responsible  for— the  delegation  of  discretionary  powers  to  government 


376  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

agencies.    These  groups  maintain  an  ever-watchful  eye  upon  administrative 
decisions  affecting  their  own  purposes  and  programs.14 

Their  influence  is  exercised  through  requests  for  information;  demands 
to  be  heard  at  formal  hearings;  their  ability  to  create  an  extremely  un- 
favorable atmosphere  of  publicity  for  the  agency;  and  a  negative  power  of 
refusing  to  cooperate  with  administrative  officials.  Over  and  above  pres- 
sure tactics,  however,  as  was  pointed  out  in  an  earlier  chapter,15  group  or- 
ganizations have  secured  considerable  recognition  for  a  valuable  consulta- 
tive role  through  which,  in  various  forms,  they  may  participate  in  the 
formulation  of  administrative  policy. 

Public  Relations.  Public  relations,  not  only  with  legislative  bodies  and 
organized  groups  but  also  in  terms  of  informing  the  press  and  the  general 
public  of  the  work  and  accomplishments  of  an  agency,  have  been  accepted 
in  recent  years  as  an  essential  element  in  administrative  policy.16  While  the 
general  function  of  a  public-relations  officer  is  one  of  public  information,  his 
influence  extends  to  the  problem  of  how  a  complicated,  technical  policy-de- 
cision can  best  be  explained  to  the  lay  public.  Sometimes  he  may  have  to 
propose  the  modification  of  a  policy  in  order  to  secure  better  understanding 
and  a  more  favorable  public  attitude  toward  the  agency. 

Beyond  its  decisions  in  particular  cases,  the  long-run  task  of  an  admin- 
istrative agency  is  a  public-relations  problem.  The  job  is  to  transform  a 
public  policy,  which  originally  is  only  a  string  of  words  in  the  statute  book 
or  in  a  directive,  from  a  purely  verbal  expression  into  a  pattern  of  public 
acceptance.  Such  acceptance  must  include  an  expectancy  as  to  the  activities 
of  officials  responsible  for  putting  the  policy  into  effect.  In  this  broadest 
sense  of  public  relations,  the  long-run  justification  of  an  administrative 
agency — particularly  in  the  regulatory  field — will  depend  in  large  measure 
upon  its  success  in  establishing  a  favorable  reaction  to  its  basic  policies  and 
its  normal  methods  of  operation. 

Issues  of  Legality.  Since  government  agencies  function  in  pursuance  of 
law  and  are  controlled  through  forms  of  law  imposed  by  the  courts,  legal 
considerations  are  an  important  factor  in  administrative  policy-making. 
Many  agencies  have  a  continuing  problem,  however,  in  clarifying  for  them- 
selves the  proper  role  of  legal  advice.  The  term  "administrative  law"  may 
be  said  to  include  the  legal  rules  controlling  administration,  the  written 
letter  of  the  policies  developed  for  or  by  administration,  and  the  procedural 
forms  through  which  administrative  acts  secure  legal  effect.  One  or  the 

14  Cf.  Herring,  Pendlcton,  Public  Administration  and  the  Public  Interest,  New  York: 
McGraw-Hill,  1936;  Crawford,  K.,  The  Pressure  Boys,  New  York:  Viking,  1939;  McCunc,  W., 
The  Farm  Bloc,  New  York:  Harcourt  Brace,  1943;  Blaisdell,  D.  C.,  Economic  Power  and 
Political  Pressures,  Monograph  No.  26  of  the  Temporary  National  Economic  Committee,  Wash- 
ington: Government  Printing  Office,  1941. 

*8  Cf.  Ch.  14,  'Interest  Groups  in  Administration." 

**  Cf.  McCamy,  James  L.f  Governmental  Publicity,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press, 
1939. 


THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  377 

other  of  these  highly  important  aspects  of  the  administrative  process  has  upon 
occasion  been  used  to  justify  the  notion  that  legal  considerations— that  is, 
those  proposed  by  lawyers — should  dominate  in  the  determination  of  sub- 
stantive policy  and  likewise  in  the  entire  process  of  administrative  investi- 
gation and  review. 

Task  of  the  Agency  Lawyer.  For  example,  in  the  early  wartime  history 
of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,17  virtually  a  dual  legal-administrative 
structure  was  established.  A  legal  adviser  reporting  to  the  general  counsel 
of  OPA  was  attached  to  each  important  level  of  authority  in  the  Price 
Department.  To  require  legal  consultation  may  not  appear  to  be  an  onerous 
obligation.  However,  when  it  is  construed  by  either  the  operators  in  the 
line  of  command  or  the  lawyers,  or  by  both,  as  a  division  of  administrative 
responsibility,  a  truly  perplexing  situation  arises.  Similarly,  at  higher  policy 
levels  operating  executives  tend  to  resent  the  views  of  the  chief  legal  counsel 
on  policy  proposals  unless  these  center  on  questions  of  authority;  adequacy 
of  analysis  of  the  legal  issues;  accuracy  of  the  facts  upon  which  the  proposed 
determination  is  based;  and  propriety  of  the  form  and  procedure  in  which 
action  is  to  be  taken. 

Of  these  four  categories,  questions  of  authority  afford  perhaps  the  least 
numerous  though  the  most  irritating  opportunities  for  participating  in  policy 
discussion.  In  administration,  the  most  sought-after  advice  relates  to  the 
questions:  "What  should  be  done?"  and  "How  can  this  be  done?"  It  is  a 
great  temptation  for  the  lawyer,  particularly  if  he  is  able  and  aggressive, 
to  overextend  his  sphere  in  initiating  policy  on  administrative  matters.  In 
most  situations  he  will  contribute  to  internal  administrative  unity  and  im- 
proved public  relations  if  he  raises  his  policy  ideas  and  legal  questions 
reasonably  close  to  the  final  point  of  determination.  In  so  doing,  he  will 
make  his  influence  less  questionable  and  secure  more  respect  for  the  con- 
siderations that  fall  into  his  primary  responsibility  for  litigation  before  the 
courts  and  proper  deference  to  the  citizen's  procedural  interests. 

Dynamics  of  Administrative  Policy-Making.  All  of  these  external  factors 
are  dependent  upon  one  another.  In  more  than  one  way  they  are  involved  in 
most  policy  determinations,  with  their  importance  varying  from  problem  to 
problem.  Giving  each  factor  its  proper  weight  is  the  function  of  adminis- 
trative judgment.  Policy  decision  in  administration  is  not  an  isolated  act 
of  top  officials;  it  is  not  a  legalistic  interpretation  of  an  hypothetical  legis-i 
lative  intent;  nor  is  it  the  exercise  of  unfettered  power  to  steer  a  course 
according  to  the  administrator's  political  preferences  or  social  prejudices. 
Rather,  it  is  the  result  of  an  interplay  of  many  forces  and  many  brains 
brought  to  a  focus  by  the  coordinating  direction  from  the  administrator. 

17  See  Pniefer,  C.  H.,  "Dual  Responsibility  under  a  Single  Head,"  Public  Administration 
Review,  1943,  Vol.  3,  pp.  59-60.  C/.  in  general  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "The  Lawyer's  Role  in 
Public  Administration,"  Y*te  Law  Journal.  1946,  Vol.  55,  p.  498  ff. 


378  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

His  is  the  responsibility  for  reconciling  political  and  legal  factors  with  the 
factual  analyses  and  technical  recommendations  of  his  staff. 

The  dynamics  of  administrative  policy-making  are  therefore  not  readily 
captured  in  any  simple  pattern  of  thought.  The  least  realistic  view  is  that 
of  administrative  policy  emerging  straight  from  the  administrator's  autono- 
mous decision.  The  gifted  executive,  it  is  true,  will  be  able  to  sense  the 
need  for  policy  shifts  as  well  as  the  weaknesses  in  existing  policy  through 
his  grasp  of  the  work  of  his  organization.  Even  then,  however,  he  will 
combat  any  tendency  on  his  part  to  come  forth  spontaneously  with  specific 
remedies.  Instead,  he  will  be  guided  by  personal  "hunch"  to  probe  into  the 
matter  in  conversations  with  his  immediate  associates,  and  on  this  basis 
determine  specific  assignments  of  an  exploratory  character  addressed  to  ap- 
propriate staff  units  or  line  officials.  Their  preliminary  work  in  turn  will 
furnish  the  basis  upon  which  the  particular  problem  can  be  discussed  a 
second  time  with  better  insight  on  the  top  level. 

Far  more  often  are  policy  proposals  initiated,  not  by  the  administrator 
himself,  but  by  those  much  further  down  the  line  who  see  the  issues  in  con- 
crete terms  in  the  course  of  their  day-by-day  activities.  A  field  office  chief, 
for  instance,  may  grow  aware  of  the  operating  inadequacy  of  a  given  policy. 
He  may  have  informal  ways  of  checking  his  own  reactions  with  those  of 
other  field  officers  in  his  region.  He  is  also  in  a  position  to  take  into  ac- 
count public  attitudes  in  his  area  expressed  to  him  in  various  ways,  includ- 
ing occasional  lunches  with  local  spokesmen  of  his  agency's  clientele  and 
other  interested  groups.  Through  his  reporting  relationships  with  the 
regional  director,  he  has  an  opportunity  for  enlisting  the  latter's  interest. 
Again,  a  broadening  of  relevant  considerations  is  apt  to  occur  when  the 
emerging  proposal  and  the  substantiating  facts  are  mulled  over  in  the  re- 
gional office,  or  perhaps  placed  on  the  agenda  of  some  periodic  meeting  of 
all  field  officers  held  by  the  regional  head.  As  the  matter  moves  up  the 
line,  it  is  likely  to  reach  the  departmental  level  in  the  context  of  an  indi- 
vidual bureau  responsible  for  defined  aspects  of  the  agency's  program. 
Ordinarily,  the  bureau  chief  will  first  assure  himself  of  the  thoughts  of  his 
own  key  people.  Only  thereafter  will  he  draw  other  bureaus  or  staff  units 
into  consultation. 

Perhaps  the  bureau  chief  will  have  sufficient  standing  before  the  legis- 
lature to  take  the  initiative  in  sounding  out  some  of  the  more  important 
figures  on  the  legislative  committee  that  is  primarily  concerned  with  the 
agency's  activities.  He  may  thus  be  able  to  ascertain  in  advance  the  drift 
of  legislative  attitude.  He  may  also  seek  the  views  of  interest-group  head- 
quarters, either  through  formal  consultation  or  in  off-the-record  conversa- 
tions. In  all  of  these  stages  there  occurs  an  enrichment  of  thought  and  a 
sounder  appreciation  of  the  realities  surrounding  the  policy  proposal.  Such 
realities  may  well  include  gradually  sharpening  disagreements  among  dif- 


THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY  379 

ferent  interest  groups,  among  different  bureaus,  among  different  legislators, 
and  among  different  staff  officers. 

Administrative  gains  to  be  secured  by  action  on  the  proposal  would 
have  to  be  balanced  carefully  against  the  potentialities  for  internal  and  ex- 
ternal conflict.  In  many  instances,  no  doubt,  the  proposal  is  shelved  before 
it  goes  any  further.  In  other  instances,  the  sponsoring  bureau  chief  will 
grow  convinced  that  a  fuller  examination  of  the  facts  and  of  possible  alter- 
natives to  the  proposal  is  required.  Such  examination  may  involve  extensive 
study  by  a  particular  staff  unit  in  the  agency,  perhaps  in  cooperation  with  ex- 
pert staffs  in  other  agencies  and  on  the  level  of  the  chief  executive,  or  with 
private  groups  having  research  facilities  or  other  resources  of  their  own.  In 
still  other  cases,  the  matter  will  resolve  itself  in  terms  of  an  opinion  of  the 
legal  counsel  of  the  agency — negative  or  positive;  and  if  the  latter,  with 
or  without  significant  qualifications. 

All  of  this  is  merely  the  preliminary  stage  of  preparing  the  ground  for 
action  on  the  administrator's  level.  When  and  if  the  matter  comes  up 
before  him,  it  will  usually  be  clear  whether  legislative  changes  must  be 
sought  or  whether  the  issue  can  be  disposed  of  through  executive  order  or 
by  the  agency  itself  under  its  statutory  authorization.  The  administrator 
must  assure  himself  of  the  comprehensiveness  of  vision  that  should  support 
the  proposal.  His  immediate  staff  aides  will  help  him  to  determine  whether 
the  recommendation  makes  due  allowance  for  an  agency-wide  or  even 
government-wide  point  of  view,  or  whether  it  tends  to  overplay  the  insti- 
tutional interest  of  one  particular  bureau  or  one  particular  function  en- 
trusted to  the  agency.  He  may  decide  to  yield  in  this  individual  instance 
to  what  he  must  recognize  to  be  an  act  of  bureau  self-promotion — simply 
because  he  is  aware  of  the  political  strength  of  the  sponsoring  bureau  in 
terms  of  its  outside  support.  In  any  event  he  will  have  to  alert  his  public- 
relations  staff  for  the  impending  action. 

Then,  before  he  takes  action  he  may  want  to  bring  together  once  more 
the  leaders  of  interest  groups,  perhaps  in  order  to  achieve  a  more  satis- 
factory compromise  among  them  or  to  win  additional  support  through 
measured  concessions  to  opposing  interests.  If  he  does,  he  may  on  occasion 
find  it  desirable  to  drop  the  proposal  because  of  growing  fear  of  public 
controversy.  Conversely,  it  is  also  conceivable  that  for  reasons  of  personal 
conviction  or  personal  working  relationships  with  individual  legislators, 
other  agency  heads,  or  important  interest  groups  the  administrator  will  veto 
the  proposal  notwithstanding  a  climate  of  wider  support.  Furthermore, 
his  thinking  will  be  affected  by  his  own  anticipation  of  the  reaction  or  the 
needs  of  the  chief  executive. 

If  the  policy  proposal  requires  for  enactment  an  executive  order,  the 
administrator  must  give  thought  to  the  kinds  of  resistance  or  opposition  he 
may  run  into  when  the  drafted  order  enters  the  process  of  top-level  clear- 
ance. In  the  face  of  a  serious  chance  of  conflict  on  this  level  he  would  have 


380  THE  FORMULATION  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  POLICY 

to  raise  the  question  of  whether  he  should  first  discuss  the  matter  with  the 
chief  executive  or  present  it  in  a  cabinet  meeting.  Here  again,  reconcilia- 
tion and  adjustment  will  have  to  be  worked  out;  and  the  ultimate  product 
of  the  long  chain  of  transactions  may  look  quite  different  from  anything 
the  field  office  chief  had  in  mind  when  he  made  himself  the  snowball  that 
set  off  the  avalanche. 

This  much  is  clear,  however.  Administrative  policy-making  is  ordinar- 
ily not  reduced  to  any  single  action  either  of  a  homogeneous  bureaucracy 
or  of  the  responsible  administrator.  It  is  more  in  the  nature  of  a  conglom- 
eration of  agreements  among  a  large  variety  of  groups — agreements  suf- 
ficiently widespread  and  substantial  to  outweigh  remaining  unresolved 
conflicts.  It  is  a  process  that  necessarily  in  most  instances  moves  slowly, 
but  proportionately  moves  more  surely.  It  is  also  one  that  operates  at  a 
relatively  high  rate  of  mortality  of  policy  proposals.  With  all  that,  it  is  no 
less  an  approximation  of  community  consensus  than  is  the  legislative  process, 
and  it  is  subject  to  the  same  irritations  and  handicaps. 


CHAPTER 

17 

Government  By  Procedure 

1.  THE  NATURE  AND  LIMITATIONS  OF  PROCEDURE 

Meaning  of  Procedure.  In  the  hectic  early  days  of  one  of  the  great  war 
agencies  of  World  War  II,  the  handling  of  correspondence  was  so  cumber- 
some and  slow  that  often  tempers  reached  the  blazing  point.  A  well-known 
management  analyst,  brought  in  to  help  treat  the  agency's  growing  pains, 
made  a  study  of  the  routine  steps  in  dealing  with  a  simple  letter  from  the 
time  it  reached  the  office  until  the  equally  simple  one-paragraph  reply  was 
mailed.  A  very  unusual  but  dramatic  "flow  chart"  was  prepared,  using 
a  thirty-yard  strip  of  wrapping  paper  and — symbolically — festoons  of  red 
tape  to  indicate  the  tortuous  movements  of  the  correspondence,  step  by  step. 
As  a  result  of  the  study,  replies  were  speeded  and  manpower  and  materials 
were  saved,  chiefly  through  the  introduction  of  standardized  procedures  to 
deal  with  routine  inquiries. 

This  incident  serves  to  illustrate  some  of  the  matters  that  are  the  subject 
of  our  discussion  here — such  as  the  relationship  of  procedures  to  staff  morale 
and  "public  relations,"  and  the  value  of  specialization  in  the  analysis  and 
creation  of  procedure. 

Administrative  procedure,  broadly  defined,  is  the  prescribed  or  custom- 
ary way  of  working  together  in  the  conduct  of  an  organization's  business. 
Procedure  thus  has  three  distinguishing  features.  The  first  is  the  repetition 
of  transactions  in  a  prescribed  or  customary  fashion.  The  second  is  the 
coordination  of  various  efforts  into  a  larger  whole.  The  third  is  purpose: 
to  maintain  the  organization  in  operation  and  achieve  its  goals. 

Role  of  Procedure.  The  essential  role  of  procedure  is  well  epitomized 
in  phrases  that  Walter  Bagehot  coined  for  another  purpose — "the  hyphen 
that  joins,  the  buckle  that  binds."  Aside  from  leadership  and  cooperation, 
it  is  procedure  that  knits  an  organization  into  a  whole  and  keeps  it  a  going 
concern.  It  is  procedure  that  governs  the  routine  internal  and  external 
relationships — between  one  individual  and  another;  between  one  organiza- 
tional unit  and  another;  between  one  process  and  another;  between  one 

381 


382  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

skill  or  technique  and  another;  between  one  function  and  another;  between 
one  place  and  another;  between  the  organization  and  the  public;  and  be- 
tween all  combinations  and  permutations  of  these.  It  is  by  means  of  pro- 
cedure that  the  day-to-day  work  of  government  is  done— mail  sorted,  routed 
and  delivered;  deeds  recorded;  accounts  audited;  cases  prosecuted;  protests 
heard;  food  inspected;  budgets  reviewed;  tax  returns  verified;  data  collected; 
supplies  purchased;  property  assessed;  inquiries  answered;  orders  issued; 
investigations  made;  and  so  forth  endlessly. 

Procedure,  properly  applied,  allows  specialization  to  be  carried  to  its 
optimum  degree  and  effects  the  most  efficient  division  of  labor.  Procedure 
not  only  divides  labor;  it  also  divides — and  fixes — responsibility.  Procedure 
thus  is  a  means  of  maintaining  order  and  of  achieving  regularity,  continuity, 
predictability,  control,  and  accountability.  It  is  a  means  of  maximizing  con- 
trol of  the  subjective  drives  of  an  organization's  members,  of  assuring  that 
their  official  actions  contribute — and,  if  possible,  that  their  private  loyalties 
conform — to  the  organization's  objectives.  From  a  general  political  angle, 
procedure  ensures  equality  of  treatment — a  value  of  great  significance  to  the 
citizen. 

Procedure  is  not  a  unique  feature  of  public  administration.  It  is  a  con- 
comitant of  all  organized  activity,  and  many  procedures  are  equally  usable 
by  private  administration  or  public  administration.  Private  as  well  as  pub- 
lic "red  tape"  can  be  time-consuming  and  annoying  to  those  affected,  as 
any  one  can  testify  who  has  tried  to  exchange  a  purchase  without  a  sales 
slip  or  to  cash  a  check  without  "proper  identification."1 

Procedures  as  Laws  of  Activity.  From  one  point  of  view,  an  organiza- 
tion's procedures  may  be  regarded  as  a  body  of  "law"  applying  primarily 
to  its  members,  but  also  in  varying  degree  and  manner — depending  upon 
the  organization's  authority  and  activities — to  persons  outside.  More  than 
analogy  is  involved.  -  To  the  extent  that  procedures  are  prescribed  by  con- 
stitution, statute,  and  court  decision,  they  are  law  in  the  full  legal  sense 
and  they  are  enforceable  as  such.  "Most  procedures,  however,  are  only  modes 
o^conduct  devised  by  the  organization  to  regulate  the  working  relations 
of  its  members.  While  these  modes  of  conduct  must,  of  course,  be  consonant 
with  law,  and  while  in  the  case  of  public  agencies  their  ultimate  purpose 
may  be  to  give  effect  to  law,  they  are  not  generally  law  in  the  technical 
sense.  The  sanctions  for  their  enforcement  are  primarily  administrative. 

As  with  law,  procedure  may  be  either  written  or  unwritten.  Large  and 
well-developed  agencies  have  specialized  procedure-issuing  organs  and  put 
forth  a  large  volume  of  written  procedural  materials.  Small  and  rudi- 
mentary organizations  may  rely  heavily  upon  unwritten  custom.  In  any 
organization,  large  or  small,  custom  and  current  conceptions  of  adminis- 
trative right  and  wrong  are  very  important.  Some  written  procedures,  just 

*For  an  interesting  comparison  of  public  and  private  "red  tape,"  see  Appleby,  Paul  H., 
Kg  Democracy,  Ch.  6,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  383 

as  some  laws  and  ordinances,  are  honored  chiefly  in  the  breach,  though 
they  have  been  prepared  in  the  proper  manner  and  duly  signed  by  the 
highest  authority.  They  may  be  so  poorly  written  that  they  are  not  read 
or  understood;  or  so  unrealistic  that  they  are  not  taken  seriously;  or  they 
may  be  contrary  to  prevailing  notions  of  administrative  morality  and  in- 
capable of  enforcement.  Conversely,  some  procedures  may  become  well- 
developed  by  custom  and  be  followed  religiously  without  being  committed 
to  paper — either  through  neglect  or  because  to  do  so  would  not  be  politic. 
"Standard  operating  procedure"  is  not  necessarily  set  forth  in  a  manual. 

Again  as  with  law,  procedure  is  laid  down  at  various  levels.  An  organi- 
zation may  prescribe  procedures  applying  to  itself  as  a  whole  or  to  any 
or  most  of  its  component  parts.  Conversely,  organizational  units  generally 
may  adopt  any  procedures  that  are  reasonable  and  not  in  conflict  with  law 
or  with  procedures  set  forth  by  a  superior  authority.  The  structure  of  pro- 
cedures in  a  large  organization  thus  resembles  a  child's  set  of  nested  blocks. 
Accordingly,  the  "man  at  the  bottom"  operates  under  several,  perhaps  many, 
layers  of  procedure.  Lest  this  be  regarded  as  cruel,  let  it  be  said  that  unless 
he  is  an  oversensitive  individual  he  is  likely  to  become  accustomed  to  his 
burden,  and  even  to  cherish  it  as  something  peculiarly  his  own. 

Procedure  as  Physiology  of  Organization.  From  another  point  of  view, 
procedure  may  be  looked  upon  as  the  "physiology"  of  organization.  As  such 
it  is  not  separable,  even  in  concept,  from  considerations  of  formal  organiza- 
tional structure.  Anatomy  and  physiology  are  but  different  aspects  of  the 
same  thing:  structure  is  meaningless  without  functions,  and  function  is 
impossible  without  structure.  Organizational  structures  are  defined  ulti- 
mately in  terms  of  procedures — "shall  be  the  function  of,"  "shall  report  to," 
"are  responsible  for."  And  in  turn,  procedures  are  geared  to  organizational 
structure— "upon  receipt  from  the  Administrative  Division,"  "shall  forward 
to  the  appropriate  district  office,"  and  so  forth. 

Organizations  are  structures  of  relationships  between  skills.  Procedure 
brings  the  structures  to  life.  For  highly  developed  professional  or  scientific 
skills,  procedure  performs  the  function  of  uniting  them  with  an  organization 
and  its  purposes.  It  does  not,  however,  substantially  affect  or  reach  into  the 
skills  or  techniques  of  professional  and  scientific  personnel.  The  prepara- 
tion of  a  legal  argument,  the  treatment  of  a  plant  disease,  or  the  analysis 
of  food  for  selenium  traces  are  governed  for  the  most  part  by  rules  outside 
the  realm  of  administration.  In  descending  the  scale  of  specialized  skills, 
however,  this  tends  to  be  less  and  less  true.  Eventually  a  point  is  reached 
at  which  administrative  procedure  merges  with  whatever  specialized  func- 
tion the  individual  may  perform.  Such  operations  as  sorting,  packaging,  and 
loading  are  subject  in  their  entirety  to  well-developed  techniques  of  proce- 
dure analysis  and  improvement. 

Procedure  as  Institutional  Habit.  In  still  another  aspect,  the  procedures 
of  an  organization  may  be  viewed  as  its  "habits."  Habits  are  the  repetitive 


384  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

acts  that  in  large  measure  express  and  affect  the  personality  and  character 
of  an  individual.  Procedures  are  the  repetitive  acts  that  in  large  measure 
manifest  and  shape  the  personality  and  character  of  an  organization.  Both 
habits  and  procedures  routinize  and  stabilize  day-to-day  existence,  contribute 
to  the  achievement  of  immediate  goals,  and  release  energies  to  deal  with 
what  is  novel  or  "higher." 

As  it  has  its  characteristic  merits,  habit  has  its  characteristic  disadvan- 
tages, and  it  is  here  that  the  chief  limitations  of  procedure  emerge.  For 
not  only  are  procedures  analogous  to  habits;  beyond  that,  to  an  individual 
participant  a  procedure  becomes  largely  a  habit  or  series  of  habits,  physiologi- 
cally no  different  from  habits  developed  in  private  life.  Thus  a  clerk  whose 
role  in  a  procedure  is  to  sort  and  route  certain  documents  develops  patterns 
of  mental  and  muscular  coordination  that  are  second  nature. 

The  disadvantages  of  habit  lie  in  its  propensity  to  engross  the  whole 
individual.  The  repetitive  acts  yield  psychological  and  physiological  satis- 
factions, and  the  habits  become  ends  in  themselves  and  substitutes  for 
thought  instead  of  aids  to  thought.  A  "cake  of  custom"  develops  and 
hardens,  hindering  adaptation  to  changed  circumstances.  It  is  a  common 
experience  to  encounter  a  human  being  or  an  organization  that  is  now 
only  an  animated  antique  because  habits  or  procedures  were  allowed  to 
become  ends  in  themselves  instead  of  means  to  ends. 

The  manifestations  of  procedural  hardening  of  the  administrative  arteries 
are  undesirable  in  themselves  and  dangerous  to  the  life  of  the  organization. 
Constant  effort  is  needed  to  obviate  this  deterioration.  By  its  very  nature, 
procedure  limits  initiative  and  narrows  discretion.  Unless  the  individuals 
concerned  are  more  than  ordinarily  vigorous  and  resourceful,  aware  of  the 
role  of  procedure  and  trained  in  its  analysis,  procedures— even  excellent 
ones — exact-sutoll.  • 

Some  victims  of  procedure,  feeling  their  ambitions  unsatisfied  and  their 
egos  suppressed,  adopt  the  tactic  of  passive  resistance.  They  develop  a 
"waitiogjor.  orders"  outlook,  and  pull  only  enough  to  keep  the  traces  taut. 
Others  make  a  false  virtue  of  what  appears  a  necessity  by  developing  a 
Cult  of  Procedure.  Unsure  of  their  position,  uninformed  about  the  signifi- 
cance of  their  function  in  the  whole  procedural  system,  they  magnify,  their 
task  far  beyond  its  intrinsic  importance.  Their  own  procedural  role  becomes 
a  Thing-in-Itself,  a  monstrous  defense  mechanism.  Procedure  is  turned 
into  a  weapon  to  ward  off  the  criticism  of  outsiders— ignorant  intruders  who 
do  not  recognize  the  preeminence  of  Procedure.  Woe  betide  the  soul,  inside 
the  organization  or  out,  who  slights  or  fails  to  live  by  Procedure! 

Still  others,  at  once  sophisticated  about  procedure  and  indifferent  to  the 
ends  it  is  designed  to  serve,  will  use  it  as  an  army  uses  fortifications,  either 
as  a  basefor  attack  or  a  situs  for  defense.  If  action  or  inaction  serves  their 
interests,  mey  either  will  find  a  way  to  fit  it  within  the  letter  of  the  pro- 
cedures or  they  will  circumvent  or  violate  them.  But  if  they  are  faced  with 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  385 

an  action  they  personally  find  disagreeable,  even  the  minutiae  of  procedure 
will  be  used  to  strangle  and  kill. 

2.  PROCEDURES  AND  PUBLIC  ADMINISTRATION 

Rule  of  Law.  Although  procedure  has  generic  qualities  that  do  not  differ 
whether  the  organization  is  public  or  private,  the  objectives  of  public 
administration  and  the  conditions  under  which  it  is  carried  on  create  spe- 
cial procedural  functions  and  problems.  American  public  administration 
aims  at  the  accomplishment  of  broad,  diverse,  and  often  intangible  objec- 
tives while  working  within  the  framework  of  one  of  the  most  complex 
legal  systems  of  any  modern  state.  It  does  this  over  great  spaces — in  the 
midst  of  a  large,  heterogeneous,  and  in  part  unsympathetic  population;  and 
in  interrelation  with  an  economic  system  of  unparalleled  intricacy. 

The  broad,  diverse,  and  often  intangible  objectives  of  public  administra- 
tion are  in  large  degree  set  forth  in  the  statutes  creating  and  instructing 
particular  agencies.  However,  in  pursuing  the  objectives  laid  down  in  its 
basic  statute  an  agency  is  motivated  and  guided  not  only  by  the  statute 
itself.  As  a  governmental  entity,  its  actions  are  conditioned  by  many  other 
legal  provisions  which  in  one  way  or  another  apply  to  it.  These  provisions 
are  many  because  the  constitutional-legal  system  of  America  is  of  great 
complexity. 

The  fundamental  significance  of  our  complex  legal  system  for  actions 
which  affect  the  public  lies  primarily  in  the  idea  of  the  "rule  of  law" — the 
I  idea  that  governmental  actions  may  not  be  arbitrary  but  must  proceed  from 
and  be  consonant  with  law.  This  general  idea  has  been  imbedded  in  the 
traditions  of  Western  civilization  for  many  centuries  and  is  by  no  means 
a  unique  possession  of  America.  However,  a  number  of  factors  have  com- 
bined here  to  give  it  a  full  and  elaborate  institutional  and  legal  embodi- 
ment— so  full  and  elaborate  that  sometimes  the  ends  of  justice  may  seem 
obstructed  by  it.  The  relationship  of  public  administration  to  the  rule  of  law 
is  the  subject  of  many  volumes.  It  is  not  the  present  subject  of  discussion.2 
Here,  it  is  sufficient  to  note  some  of  the  chief  features  in  the  pattern  of 
conformity  required  of  public  administration,  and  the  role  of  procedure 
in  achieving  that  pattern. 

Every  administrative  act — national,  state,  or  local — must  conform  to  the 
Constitution  of  the  United  States  as  interpreted  by  the  courts,  ultimately 
the  Supreme  Court.  State  and  local  administrative__acts  must,  in  addition, 
accord  with  the  constitution  of  the  state  and  the  organic  law  of  the  com- 
munity concerned.  Not  only  must  administrative  acts  be  in  harmony  with 
constitutional  provisions;  they  must  also  be  in  accord  with  the  laws  which 
have  been  enacted  pursuant  to  the  constitution  concerned. 

2  For  a  review  of  this  subject  and  a  guide  to  the  literature  of  the  field,  see  Pennock,  J. 
Roland,  Administrationand  the  Rule  of  Law,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rinehart,  1941.  Sec  also 
below  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 


386  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

Safeguarding  Liberty  and  Equality.  The  Constitution  of  the  United 
States  and  those  of  the  states  individually,  and  many  of  the  federal  and 
state  laws,  contain  provisions  designed  to  safeguard  citizens  from  unjust 
and  arbitrary  actions — that  is,  to  assure  the  "rule  of  law"  in  its  moral 
content,  in  its  substance.  What  is  the  moral  content,  the  substantive  mean- 
ing, of  the  rule  of  law?  A  brief  answer  may  be  made:  liberty  and  equality. 
Ac  to  liberty,  federal  and  state  constitutions  and  laws  are  studded  with  pro- 
visions seeking  to  guarantee  that  certain  impositions  shall  not  be  made 
upon  individuals  by  government  action,  or  that  if  they  do  happen  they 
shall  happen  only  in  a  certain  prescribed  manner,  by  "due-process  of  law." 
Examples  are  the  provisions  guaranteeing  freedom— o£. expression,  or  the 
rules  of  court  procedure  designed  to  safeguard  the  rights  of  those  accused 
of  crimes.  As  to^equajity,  constitutions  and  laws  are  likewise  replete  with 
provisions  seeking  to  make  sure  that  all  persons  shall  be  treated  equally 
by  government;  or  that  if  classifications  are  established  these  shall  be  rea- 
sonable with  treatment  equal  within  classes.  Thus  there  are  provisions 
securing  for  every  one  "equal  protection  of  the  laws." 

These  limitations  upon  administration  are  political  as  well  as  legal.  It 
is  not  only  that  the  ideas_of  liberty  and  equality  are  anchored  in  the  laws. 
They  are  also  deeply  ing*amed  in  our  national  psychology  and  are  hence 
a  political  force  to  be  reckoned  with.  Public  agencies  are  often  not  free  to 
take  expeditious  actions  or  to  make  distinctions  in  treatment  that  are  within 
the  requirements  of  the  law — and  that  a  private  concern  would  take  without 
hesitation.  The  reason  is  that  to  do  so  might  raise  a  hue  and  cry  of 
"dictatorship"  that  might  imperil  the  very  existence  of  the  agency. 

The  ways  in  which  procedure  serves  to  ensure  that  the  requirements 
of  the  "rule  of  law"  are  met  are  manifold.  Probably  most  prominent  arc 
consultation  and  review  in  their  various  forms.  Consultation — intra-agency, 
interagency,  and  extragovernmental — in  proper  procedural  form  goes  far  to 
make  certain  that  regulations  and  decisions  are  both  legal  and  politic.  Pro- 
cedures for  administrative  review  of  protested  actions  arc  constantly  being 
improved  and  lessen  appeals  to  the  courts.  Procedures  for  internal  review 
of  correspondence,  orders,  and  other  official  documents  ojten  take  an  undue 
toll  of  time  and  temper  of  personnel.  Yet,  adequately  safeguarded  by  limi- 
tations on  types  of  review  and  on  time  for  review,  "clearance"  performs  an 
invaluable  function  in  contributing  to  administrative  legality  and  propriety. 

Legislative  Prescription  of  Procedure.  In  seeking  to  assure  that  adminis- 
trative procedures  are  consonant  with  and  adapted  to  serve  the  ends  of 
constitutional  government,  American  legislative  bodies  often  prescribe  pro- 
cedures in  greater  or  lesser  detail,  rather  than  leave  the  matter  to  the  dis- 
cretion of  administrators.  Legislation  may,  for  example,  direct  that  an 
agency  issue  orders  only  after  consulting  with  the  affected  individual  or 
group,  or  provide  a  review  only  for  certain  types  of  contested  decisions, 
Of  necessity,  however,  such  procedural  instructions  are  set  forth  in  phraseol- 


GOVERNMENT  B¥  PROCEDURE  387 

ogy  less  subtle  than  the  facts  that  confront  the  agency.  There  is  a  large 
area  in  which  the  agency  is  "on  its  own"  in  devising  procedures  for 
achieving  its  particular  objectives  within  legal  and  political  limits.  A  con- 
siderable limitation  of  this  area  of  option  has  been  attempted  by  the  Ad- 
ministrative Procedure  Act  of  1946,  about  which  more  will  be  said  in  a 
later  chapter. 

In  the  case  of  regulatory  agencies,  the  creation  of  procedures  is  of  special 
significance  because  the  procedures  followed  affect  the  "substance"  of  law 
in  spelling  out  the  rights  and  duties  of  individuals.  Often,  in  fact,  it  is 
only  through  procedures  that  the  intent  of  the  basic  statute  with  respect 
to  particular  conditions  is  manifested.  In  the  statutes  governing  regulatory 
agencies,  even  when  carefully  drawn,  we  find  rather  broad  criteria  of  action, 
such  as  "public  convenience  and  necessity,"  "fair  and  equitable,"  or  "unfair 
methods  of  competition."  Criteria  like  these  are  translated  by  administrative 
determination  into  specific  substantive  rules  or  decisions— that  is  to  say, 
rules  or  decisions  to  the  effect  that  certain  categories  of  persons  or  enter- 
prises may  or  must  take  or  refrain  from  specified  actions. 

In  translating  the  general  criterion  into  the  particular  rule  or  decision, 
procedures  must  be  carefully  devised  to  ensure  reasonableness,  fairness,  and 
consistency.  Or,  from  another  point  of  view,  they  must  ensure  that  all  rules 
and  decisions  are  within  the  intent  of  the  legislature  and  will  be  upheld  if 
challenged  in  the  courts.  The  "meaning"  of  a  regulatory  statute  as  it  is 
applied  depends  thoroughly  and  intimately  upon  procedural  rules  relating 
to  the  collection  of  data  or  evidence,  review  of  proposed  regulations,  appeals 
from  decisions,  and  so  forth. 

In  addition  to  laying  down  procedures  designed  to  maintain  the  "rule  of 
law,"  legislative  bodies  often  prescribe  such  procedures  for  somewhat  differ- 
ent purposes.  Conceiving  their  role  as  that  of  a  "board  of  directors"  for 
the  public's  business,  they  attempt  to  control  the  management  of  that  busi- 
ness by  defining  the  manner  in  which  it  shall  be  carried  on,  particularly 
in  matters  relating  to  personnel  and  expenditure  of  funds.  In  part  this 
may  be  ascribed  to  the  fact  that  under  our  constitutional  system,  legislative 
bodies  try  to  compensate  for  their  very  limited  ability  to  choose  or  remove 
a  chief  executive.  They  are  therefore  prone  to  supervise  executive  actions 
in  as  great  detail  as  possible.  In  part,  also,  it  may  be  ascribed  to  the  special 
honesty,  publicity,  and  propriety  expected  in  the  conduct  of  public  busi- 
ness. As  a  nation  we  have  a  double  standard  of  administrative  virtue, 
one  for  private  organizations  and  one  for  public.  As  a  result,  legis- 
lators— and  sometimes  administrators — in  a  well-meant  attempt  to  "keep 
out  of  trouble"  tend  to  create  substantive  vices  by  excesses  of  procedural 
virtue. 

Protecting  Administrative  Morality.  Dishonesty  in  public  places  is  news. 
Since  the  merest  peccadillos  may  come  through  magnification  in  the  press 
to  influence  policy,  public  financial  and  personnel  procedures  are  hedged 


388  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

about  by  a  great  mass  of  stipulations  designed  to  attain,  not  speed  and 
efficiency  in  the  public's  business,  but  honesty  to  the  letter  and  accuracyjto 
the  cent.3  The  same  is  true  of  procurement  of  supplies,  which  is  potentially 
and  sometimes  actually  subject  to  serious  abuse.  To  prevent  dishonesty, 
elaborate  safeguards  have  been  erected.  Thus  government  agencies  are  in- 
duced to  regard  purchasing  of  supplies  as  a  routine  clerical  operation  that 
can  be  performed  by  any  one  who  has  mastered  the  many  relevant  laws, 
regulations,  and  forms,  rather  than  a  business  calling  for  skill  in  the 
economics  of  supply. 

The  criteria  of  success  under  such  conditions  are  apt  to  relate  more  to 
the  correctness  of  the  paperwork  or  the  absence  of  "exceptions"  taken  by 
the  supervisory  authority,  and  less  to  cost  and  quality.  Of  course,  honesty 
is  essential.  It  is  a  prime  question,  however,  whether  there  is  not  a  basic 
deficiency  in  laws  and  rules  that  fail  to  encourage  an  efficient  stewardship 
of  the  public  interest  and  on  the  contrary  lend  an  aura  of  respectability  to 
limited  vision  and  dullness. 

As  citizens,  we  demand  that  propriety  as  well  as  honesty  in  public 
business  be  doubly  served  by  administrative  procedures.  For  example — per- 
haps as  a  survival  of  the  notion  that  "the  king  can  do  no  wrong" — letters 
from  the  government  are  expected  to  be  not  only  precise  and  definitive  in 
substantive  commitments  but  also  models  of  correctness.  So  the  Bureau  of 
Widgets  perforce  must  maintain  a  foolproof  correspondence-review  proce- 
dure to  ensure  neat  and  grammatical  replies  even  to  messy  and  ungrammati- 
cal  letters,  despite  the  inevitable  delay. 

Aims  of  Procedure.  Clearly,  the  public  character  of  public  administra- 
tion generates  special  problems  in  the  creation  and  revision  of  procedures. 
At  the  bare  minimum,  administrative  procedures  must  be  above  a  legiti- 
mate charge  of  unconstitutionally  or  illegality.  If  they  are  good  procedures, 
they  will  do  much  more.  "They  will  aim  to  conform  to  the  spirit  as  well  as 
the  letter  of  our  basic  guarantees  of  freedom  and  equality.  They  will  seek 
under  unusjaally  difficult  circumstances  to  reconcile  honesty  with  speed  and 
efficiency.  They  will  go  beyond  the  requirements  of  law  in  providing  for 
prompt  and  courteous  treatment  of  the  citizen. 

The  public  official  is  like  the  preacher's  wife  in  that  higher  than  usual 
standards  of  morality,  propriety,  and  courtesy  are  deemed  to  apply  to  both. 
In  an  economic  sense  there  may  be  no  distinction  between  the  sources  of 
public  and  private  salaries,  but  the  Taxpayers'  League  will  never  believe  it. 

3.  TYPES  OF  ADMINISTRATIVE  PROCEDURES 

Classes  of  Procedures.  A  Linnaeus  who  will  analyze  and  classify  the  flora 
of  the  procedural  realm  has  yet  to  appear.  For  some  reason,  formal  analysis 
in  this  realm  has  lagged  behind  that  in  the  realm  of  organization.  Perhaps 

8  A  lively  discussion  of  limitations  of  this  type  will  be  found  in  Juran,  J.  M.,  Bureaucracy: 
A  Challenge  to  Better  Management,  ch.  5,  New  York:  Harper,  1944. 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  389 

this  indicates  only  that  no  constructive  purpose  would  be  served  by  classi- 
fication. Perhaps  it  indicates  lack  of  courage  and  industry,  for  procedural 
issuances  exhibit  a  forbidding  tropical  exuberance  and  diversity. 

Administrative  procedures  can  obviously  be  classified  upon  a  purely 
formal  basis  in  several  ways-— for  instance,  whether  written  or  unwritten, 
whether  issued  centrally  or  by  field  offices,  and  so  on.  However,  the  formal 
classification  which  seems  most  significant,  in  terms  of  the  sources  and  uses 
of  administrative  procedures,  is  one  which  distinguishes  between  procedures 
designed  to  keep  the  organization  operating  as  an  organization,  and  those 
designed  to  accomplish  the  particular  objectives  of  the  organization.  The 
former  are  internal  and  purely  "institutional."  They  are  not  issued  to  the 
public.  The  latter,  being  concerned  with  the  specific  job  of  the  organization, 
vary  greatly.  They  are  of  two  main  types:  those  affecting  a  public  and 
issued  publicly,  and  those  issued  and  applying  internally  only. 

Institutional  Procedures.  Institutional  administrative  procedures  in  our 
sense  are  those  pertaining  to  a  staff,  housekeeping,  service,  or  auxiliary 
function.4  As  noted  earlier,  such  procedures  for  public  agencies  are  in  a 
large — and  even  undesirably  large — measure  prescribed  by  statute,  though 
in  practice  the  procedures  of  various  agencies  operating  under  the  same 
statutory  prescriptions  may  vary  considerably.  Some  of  the  institutional 
procedures  of  each  agency  are  also  likely  to  emanate  from  a  central  unit 
operating  upon  a  government-wide  basis — in  the  federal  government  the 
Civil  Service  Commission,  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Treasury,  or  General 
Accounting  Office.  Among  the  matters  usually  covered  by  institutional 
procedures  are:  mail  and  communications;  meetings  and  conferences; 
travel;  internal  reporting;  preparation,  issuance  and  distribution  of  docu- 
ments; space;  library  service;  files  and  records;  clerical  services;  procure- 
ment; clearance  and  review;  budgetary  and  fiscal  administration;  and  per- 
sonnel administration  in  all  its  aspects — recruitment,  classification,  leave 
and  attendance,  compensation  and  promotions,  and  so  forth. 

The  range  and  complexity  of  these  procedures  may  well  be  illustrated 
by  the  travel  regulations.  In  the  federal  government  the  travel  regulations 
prescribed  for  all  agencies  run  to  many  thousands  of  words.  They  deal  in 
great  detail  with  such  matters  as  receiving  authority  to  travel;  permissible 
accommodations;  special  conveyances;  use  of  telephone  and  telegraph;  cal- 
culation of  per  diem  allowance;  and  use  of  various  forms,  a  minimum  of 
three  in  any  case — travel  authorization  form,  travel  request  form,  expense 
voucher  form. 

Wording  Procedures.  Procedures  designed  to  accomplish  an  agency's 
particular  objectives  are  divisible  into  those  oublicly  and  those  not  publicly 

4  In  its  general  meaning,  "staff"  includes  most  or  all  of  the  other  functions  enumerated 
here;  see  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  of  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Line  and  Staff."  If 
the  meaning  of  "staff"  is  more  sharply  confined  to  thinking  and  plan-making,  related  func- 
tions to  control  or  ease  operations  stand  out  as  separate  entities. 


390  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

issued.  Procedures  that  are  issued  publicly  constitute  a  set  of  "ground  ttilcs0 
for  the  agency  and  any  individual  affected  by  the  basic  statute.  They  rep- 
resent the  agency's  sense  of  the  procedural  requirements  of  the  law,  per- 
haps after  judicial  test,  and  also  its  conception  of  what  is  customary,  fair, 
and  expedient  where  the  law  is  not  explicit.  In  general,  publicly  issued 
procedural  materials. indicate  the  manner  in  which  agencies  may  reach  and 
apply  substantive  decisions;  set  forth  the  part  the  affected  persons  may  take 
or  are  required  to  take  in  connection  with  substantive  determinations;  and 
stipulate  the  remedies  and  appeals,  short  of  the  courts,  available  to  affected 
persons. 

Specifically,  such  procedural  issuances  deal  with  consultations  and  con- 
ferences with  interest  groups;  adversary  proceedings;  investigations;  exami- 
nations; petitions;  reports  and  records  as  a  basis  for  findings;  hearings; 
official  notice;  written  evidence;  oral  argument;  briefs  and  pleadings;  depo- 
sitions; subpoenas;  and  administrative  review.  They  often  contain  forms 
to  be  filled  out  and  utilized.  Ideally,  they  should  tell  all  persons  affected 
by  the  basic  statute  "what^  where,  when,  and  how"  in  simple  language. 

Mention  of  "substantive"  decisions  or  determinations  requires  a  word 
of  explanation.  Many  of  the  regulations,  orders,  and  decisions  issued  by 
public  agencies  are  primarily  substantive  rather  than  procedural.  That  is 
to  say,  they  purport  to  state  the  intent-or  substance  of  the  law  as  applied 
to  a  given  set  of  facts.  Such  are  decisions  of  public  utility  commissions  or 
"cease  and  desist"  orders  issued  by  the  Federal  Trade  Commission.  Often 
the  dividing  line  between  substantive  and  procedural  issuances  is  not  at 
all  distinct.  In  some,  procedural  and  substantive  provisions  are  actually 
commingled.  Thus  Treasury  regulations  under  a  particular  tax  law  may 
contain,  without  formal  distinction  between  them,  procedural  instructions 
and  substantive  provisions  supplementing  specific  sections  of  the  law.5 

Publicly  issued  procedures  in  the  nature  of  "ground  rules"  give  the  key 
to  the  most  important  category  of  internally  issued  procedures  designed  to 
achieve  an  agency's  objectives.  For  each  important  procedural  issuance 

5  To  obviate  another  possible  source  of  confusion,  it  should  be  noted  that  "administrative 
procedure"  is  sometimes  given  a  much  narrower  meaning  than  that  given  it  in  this  discussion. 
A  considerable  number  of  students  whose  backgrounds  and  interests  are  primarily  legal  use 
the  term  "administrative  procedure"  to  refer  only  to  the  procedures  of  regulatory  agencies  in 
applying  their  statutes  to  affected  persons.  This  narrower  usage  derives  from  the  use  of  the 
word  "administrative"  to  apply  only  to  agencies  which  have  "the  power  to  determine,  cither 
by  rule  or  decision,  private  rights  and  obligations."  See  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Ad- 
ministrative Procedure,  Administrative  Procedure  in  Government  Agencies,  p.  7,  Senate  Doc. 
No.  8,  77th  Gang.,  1st  Sess.,  1941. 

The  limitations  of  this  exclusively  legal  point  of  view  are  indicated  by  a  statement  a  few 
pages  later  (p.  19):  "The  Gommittee  has  been  impressed  by  the  frequent  reluctance  of  high 
officers,  charged  with  serious  policy-making  functions,  to  relinquish  control  over  the  most 
picayune  phases  of  personnel  and  business  management."  By  definition,  high  officers  should 
not  concern  themselves  with  "picayune"  matters.  Or  might  it  seem  to  a  lawyer  intent  upon 
his  own  specialty  that  all  matters  of  personnel  and  management  are  picayune?  In  practice,  the 
legal  aspect  of  administration  is  important  but  seldom  predominant. 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  391 

affecting  persons  outside  an  organization,  there  is  likely  to  be  issued  another 
procedural  document  to  persons  within  the  organization,  explaining  in 
greater  detail  the  part  that  they  must  play  in  the  total  operation.  For  exam- 
ple, if  a  statement  or  affidavit  is  required  of  an  individual  affected  by  the 
enforcement  of  the  law,  it  is  necessary  to  specify  the  manner  of  handling  this 
document  within  the  organization — the  officers  or  organization  units  re- 
sponsible, time  limitations  for  each  decision  or  process,  criteria  to  be  applied, 
and  methods  of  disposition.  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  the  Ad- 
ministrative Procedure  Act  of  1946  has  considerably  extended  the  range  of 
federal  procedures  that  must  be  issued  publicly. 

The  publicly  issued  procedural  regulation  and  its  internal  counterpart 
may  be  illustrated  by  considering  the  industry  advisory  committees  estab- 
lished by  some  agencies.  The  publicly  issued  regulation  will  deal  with  such 
matters  as  general  functions  and  powers  of  the  committees;  eligibility  for 
membership  and  appointment  of  members;  committee  officers  and  finances; 
meetings  and  recommendations.  The  internal  regulation  will  cover  such 
matters  as  purpose  of  committees;  when  to  establish  committees;  selection 
of  committee  members;  securing  official  approval  of  comitiittees;  invitations 
and  declinations;  public  announcements;  resignations  and  removals;  alter- 
nates; and  so  forth. 

Diversity  of  Procedures.  Internally  issued  procedures  designed  to  achieve 
an  agency's  objectives  exhibit  great  diversity.  For  each  agency  they  are 
distinctive  because  the  agency  itself  is  distinctive — in  its  organizational 
structure,  its  purposes,  its  location,  its  legal  and  administrative  tools,  its  size, 
its  clientele,  its  techniques,  or  its  personnel.  Every  organization  is  unique 
in  certain  ways  if  only  because  its  personnel,  traditions,  and  mode  of  opera- 
tions are  unique  in  their  combination.  Therefore  procedure,  as  the  struc- 
ture of  working  relations  between  all  the  components  of  an  organization,, 
must  vary  with  the  individuality  of  the  organization. 

As  diversity  is  the  distinguishing  feature  of  this  category  of  administra- 
tive  procedure,  it  is  better  to  illustrate  its  manifold  nature  than  to  attempt 
classification.  Let  us  consider,  then,  the  differences  between  the  procedures 
of  two  federal  units — the  Bureau  of  Human  Nutrition  and  Home  Econom- 
ics and  the  Bureau  of  Old-Age  and  Survivors'  Insurance. 

Two  Illustrations.  The  former  is  one  of  several  bureaus  comprising  the 
Agricultural  Research  Administration  in  the  Department  of  Agriculture. 
Its  functions  are:  research  in  foods  and  nutrition,  textiles  and  clothing,  hous- 
ing and  household  equipment,  and  family  economics;  and  summarization 
and  dissemination  of  information  in  these  fields.  In  its  research  work,  con- 
ducted upon  a  project  basis,  it  has  relationships  in  the  Washington  area 
with  the  remainder  of  the  Agricultural  Research  Administration,  and  also 
with  the  Bureau  of  Agricultural  Economics,  the  Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics, 
the  Public  Health  Service,  and  the  Bureau  of  Standards.  In  its  educational 
orogram  it  has  relationships  with  the  Extension  Service  and  the  Office  of 


392  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

Education.  It  has  no  field  organization,  but  important  research  work  is 
carried  on  throughout  the  country  on  a  basis  of  temporary  cooperation  with 
other  interested  bodies,  such  as  land-grant  colleges  and  privately  endowed 
universities.  Apart  from  its  institutional  procedures — which  it  has  generally 
in  common  with  the  larger  organization  of  which  it  is  a  part — the  proce- 
dures of  this  bureau  concern  such  matters  as  inauguration  and  approval  of 
projects;  relationships  among  its  five  functional  divisions;  presentation,  re- 
view, and  publication  of  research  findings;  and  relationships  with  the 
agencies  with  which  it  cooperates  in  research  or  publicity. 

The  Bureau  of  Old-Age  and  Survivors'  Insurance,  operating  under  the 
Social  Security  Board  in  the  Federal  Security  Agency,  is  responsible  for 
the  accomplishment  of  the  old-age  and  survivors'  insurance  provisions  of 
the  Social  Security  Act.  The  extent  of  its  operations  is  indicated  by  the  fact 
that  some  67,000,000  social-security  account  numbers  have  been  assigned 
up  to  the  present  time.  To  perform  its  functions,  a  very  extensive  field 
organization  is  necessary.  The  bureau  operates  through  the  board's  regional 
offices  and  nearly  500  field  offices  administered  directly  by  the  bureau  under 
the  general  supervision  of  the  regional  directors.  In  addition,  there  is  a 
large  central  establishment  for  the  maintenance  of  complete  and  detailed 
wage  records  for  each  insured  person. 

The  typical  procedures  of  this  bureau  concern  such  matters  as  the  assign- 
ing of  account  numbers;  investigating  and  developing  accurate  wage  data 
when  such  information  has  been  incompletely  or  incorrectly  reported  by 
employers;  verifying  and  posting  wage  reports;  accepting  and  adjudicating 
claims;  making  insurance  payments;  and  so  forth.  The  performance  of 
these  operations  upon  so  vast  a  scale  necessitates  procedures  that  are  not 
only  elaborate  but  also  meticulous  in  the  extreme,  making  use  of  the  most 
advanced  office  equipment  and  recording  and  sorting  devices. 

If  nothing  else,  our  discussion  of  types  of  administrative  procedures 
will  have  conveyed  the  impression  that  the  species  of  procedure  are  not 
distinct  and  neatly  labeled.6  Perhaps  this  conclusion  need  not  cause  con- 
cern, inasmuch  as  the  science  of  biology  is  itself  without  an  unexceptionable 
concept  of  species! 

4.  CREATION  AND  CRITERIA 

Procedure-Making  Compared  with  Policy-Making.  In  the  broad  view, 
administrative  procedures  are  conceived  and  developed  in  a  manner  similar 
to  that  of  administrative  policies.  This  is  natural  since  the  two  are  intimately 

*  Unfortunately,  the  nomenclature  of  printed  procedural  materials  is  inconsistent  and  con- 
fusing. Procedural  materials  are  usually  issued  in  serial  form,  in  which  case  they  are  known 
as  "regulations"  or  "orders";  or  in  code  form,  in  which  case  items  are  designated  by  volume, 
part,  chapter,  etc.  There  is  no  general  distinction  between  categories,  such  as  "regulations," 
"rules,"  or  "orders."  Each  agency  or  jurisdiction  uses  the  terms  in  accordance  with  its  history 
and  tastes,  distinguishing  between  various  types  of  regulations  or  orders  by  adjectives — for 
instance,  different  series  of  regulations  may  be  designated  as  "administrative,"  "general,"  "divi- 
sional," and  so  on. 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  393 

related.  Procedures  should  exist  only  to  give  effect  to  policies;  and  a  wise 
policy  decision  cannot  be  made  without  thorough  consideration  of  the  pro- 
cedural implications  of  alternatives.  As  in  the  case  of  policy  decisions,  the 
top  executive,  operating  officials,  staff  personnel,  legislative  bodies,  lawyers 
and  courts,  and  outside  interest  groups  all  affect  the  formulation  of  an 
agency's  procedures. 

Compared  with  the  formulation  of  administrative  policy,  however,  there 
are  significant  differences  in  the  roles  played  by  the  various  participants. 
The  top  executive's  role  is  proportionately  less.  His  energies  will  be  largely 
absorbed  in  activities  related — if  only  indirectly — to  the  formulation  of  the 
agency's  policies.  Unless  the  procedure  affects  all  or  a  substantial  element 
of  the  organization,  or  has  important  policy  or  public-relations  aspects,  no 
extensive  part  is  likely  to  be  played  by  the  executive  head,  except  when 
formal  clearance  discloses  disagreements.  Similarly  with  line  or  operating 
officials  generally.  Their  day-by-day  business  will  account  for  most  of  their 
time  and  thought,  and  few  of  them  will  have  interest  in  the  technicalities  of 
improved  procedures — however  much  they  may  be  irritated  by  the  inade- 
quacies of  present  procedures. 

However,  seldom  will  a  procedural  change  be  made  without  consultation 
with  or  even  the  cooperation  and  consent  of  the  operating  officials  whose 
work  the  change  affects.  The  question  whether  and  in  what  cases  they 
should  be  allowed  to  interpose  vetoes  to  procedural  changes  is  a  fertile 
source  of  internal  conflict.  Operating  officials  often  do  veto  procedural 
changes,  by  virtue  of  higher  authority  or  by  sub  rosa  methods.  In  any 
organization  there  is  covert  or  perhaps  open  competition  for  position  or 
influence,  and  victory  and  defeat  in  this  competition  are  often  manifested  in 
procedural  change — or  lack  of  change. 

As  with  the  top  executive  and  line  officials,  so  with  the  legislature  and 
interest  groups — they  claim  a  smaller  share  in  the  formation  of  procedures 
than  they  do  in  the  formation  of  policies.  Legislatures,  as  we  saw,  prescribe 
a  considerable  volume  of  "housekeeping"  procedure.  Some  of  the  indi- 
vidual agency's  chief  procedures,  too,  are  likely  to  be  laid  down  in  its 
main  statute — for  instance,  that  a  review  division  shall  handle  certain  types 
of  cases,  or  that  outside  interests  shall  be  consulted  upon  an  organized  basis. 
However,  in  any  case  there  is  a  great  bulk  of  procedural  detail  to  be 
filled  in. 

Interest_gtoups  impinge  upon  the  procedure-making  process  at  several 
points.  They  may  be  consulted  formally  on  proposed  procedure  or  its  revision; 
or  they  may  exercise  some  informal  influence,  by  virtue  of  personal  relations 
between  their  members  and  agency  officers  or  procedure-making  personnel. 
Interest  groups  make  their  interest  in  procedure  felt  most  effectively,  how- 
ever, on  the  relatively  rare  occasions  when  they  can  prevail  upon  the  legisla- 
tive body  to  change  an  agency's  procedures— perhaps  over  the  objections 
of  the  latter. 


394  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

The  place  occupied  by  the  lawyer  in  procedure-making  is  of  great 
importance,  particularly  in  regulatory  agencies.  Also,  his  role  is  often  in 
dispute.  Theoretically,  it  is  advisory  only,  even  in  the  preparation  of  proce- 
dural materials  that  affect  the  rights  and  duties  of  individuals.  Not  legal 
learning  alone,  but  knowledge  of  the  facts  and  simplicity  of  phrase  are  of 
the  essence.  Certainly,  however,  the  lawyer  has  a  legitimate  advisory  func- 
tion in  laying  out  procedures  that  must  meet  the  test  of  "due  process 
of  law." 

Procedure-Making  Units.  So  much  for  the  broad  picture,  but  what  of 
procedure-making  organs,  the  problems  they  face,  the  methods  and  criteria 
they  use  ?  The  answers  to  these  questions  must,  of  necessity,  touch  upon  many 
important  subjects.  It  should  therefore  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  special- 
ized knowledge  and  arts  of  the  procedural  analyst  are  not  fully  encom- 
passed in  our  survey.  These  will  be  dealt  with  in  a  subsequent  chapter. 

As  to  procedure-making  organs,  they  are  of  various  kinds  and  they 
exist  under  a  wide  variety  of  designations,  depending  upon  the  organization 
and  customs  of  the  agency  of  which  they  are  a  part.  Generally  speaking, 
procedure-making  organs  are  attached  in  a  staff  capacity  to  the  top  executive 
or  a  subordinate  line  official,  integrated  with  a  budget  office  or  an  adminis- 
trative-management division,  or  associated  with  or  located  in  a  planning 
organ.  A  procedure-making  organ  may  operate  on  a  government-wide 
basis  in  its  administrative  jurisdiction.  Thus  the  Civil  Service  Commission 
and  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  as  indicated  above,  perform  some  procedure- 
making  functions  for  federal  administration  generally. 

In  addition  to  special  procedure-making  units  operating  at  different 
organizational  levels  of  authority,  there  is  frequently,  particularly  in  large 
organizations,  specialization  in  types  of  procedural  work.  Usually  the 
unit  dealing  with  institutional  procedures  is  separate  from  that  dealing 
with  the  agency's  substantive  procedures.  Units  for  work  simplification  or 
standardization  of  procedures  in  such  fields  as  personnel  may  be  sepa- 
rate from  either.  Wherever  they  are  located  and  whatever  their  functions, 
it  is  important  that  the  procedure-making  organs  have  authority  equal  to 
their  tasks — and  not  only  formal  authority,  but  that  moral  authority  that 
stems  from  the  interest  and  support  of  top  management  and  from  adequate 
professional  skill.  These  last  are  two  of  the  three  most  significant  ingredi- 
ents of  good  procedural  work;  the  third  is  the  interest  and  cooperation  of 
the  personnel  affected  by  the  procedures,  particularly  the  line  executives. 

There  are  two  major  emphases  in  procedural  work.  One  is  upon  creat- 
ing new  procedures,  the  other  upon  improving  existing  procedures.  In 
either  case,  of  course,  a  new  procedure  must  also  be  tested  and  installed. 

Art  of  Making  Procedures.  He  who  creates  new  procedures  must  first 
of  all  apply  himself  diligently  to  six  questions:  What?  Why?  Who?  How? 
When?  Where?  Incisiveness  and  imagination  are  necessary.  What  does 
the  statute  say?  Where  the  statute  is  not  clear,  what  is  the  best  interprc- 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  395 

tation?  What  procedural  clues  are  offered  by  similar  organizations  doing 
similar  tasks?  Can  the  job  be  done  effectively  with  the  present  organiza- 
tion or  should  change  be  recommended?  If  a  particular  method  appears 
efficient,  can  it  be  reconciled  with  stautory  requirements?  Is  the  job  one 
that  can  be  done  best  by  using  ten  skilled  or  fifteen  unskilled  employees? 
Such  are  some  of  the  questions  for  which  answers  must  be  found. 

Intimate  knowledge  of  the  facts  is  essential,  but  hardly  less  important  is 
"writijig^up"  the  procedure.  For  this,  some  of  the  art  of  the  playwright  is 
necessary,  for  good  written  procedures  are  rather  like  the  script  of  a  good 
play.  The  "characters"  must  be  introduced  and  identified,  and  they  should 
have  an  organic  role  in  the  production.  Entrances  and  exits  must  be 
planned  with  purpose,  stage  directions  must  be  given,  and  so  forth.  Pro- 
cedural materials  should  be  brief,  clear,  and  concise.  All  the  tricks  in  the 
writers'  and  printers'  trades  should  be  employed,  for  to  learn  their  lines 
quickly  the  players  must  be  induced  to  read  them.  Unfortunately,  proce- 
dural manuals  are  frequently  as  dry  and  forbidding  as  the  Sahara.7 

Procedures  must  be  installed.  Even  the  best-written  materials  do  not 
suffice  of  themselves.  Educational  campaigns  must  be  undertaken,  incentives 
offered,  sanctions  devised,  methods  for  apprehending  violators  worked  out, 
test  runs  made  to  discover  "bugs,"  and  follow-up  inspections  planned.  All 
possible  devices  for  breaking  old  habits  and  creating  new  ones  must  be 
used. 

The  job  of  probing  and  bettering  procedures  is  in  part  the  same  as  that 
of  creating  new  procedures,  in  part  different.  It  involves  preliminary  fact- 
finding  and  planning;  analysis  of  existing  procedure;  development  of  the 
proposed  new  procedure;  and  testing,  installing,  and  following  up  the 
changed  procedure.  Determination  must  be  made,  first  of  all,  of  areas  likely 
to  be  productive  of  results.  Such  phenomena  as  mushroom  growth  of 
activities,  inexperienced  personnel,  or  consolidation  of  units  within  an  organi- 
zation indicate  areas  most  likely  to  need  analysis  and  change.  Next  comes 
reconnaissance  into  the  existing  situation,  followed  by  "softening  up,"  by 
whatever  stratagems  and  demonstrations  of  shortcomings  that  can  be  em- 
ployed. Then  corrective  action  may  be  initiated. 

Worl{  Simplification  and  Procedural  Standardization.  There  are  two 
well-recognized  types  of  programs  in  the  field  of  procedure  improvement, 
both  of  which  have  been  speeded  in  their  development  by  work  of  the 
Army  Service  Forces  during  World  War  II.  One  of  these  is  work  simpli- 
fication, which  has  as  its  chief  tools  the  work  distribution  chart,  the  process 
chart  and  the  workload  chart.  The  work  distribution  chart  is  prepared  from 
an  inventory  of  the  work  of  each  member  of  an  organization  unit  or  par- 

7  On  the  subject  of  simplifying  "official  English"  see  Flcsch,  Rudolph,  "More  About 
^"  Public  Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  pp.  240-244.  Herbert  A.  Simon's 


'The  Fine  Art  of  Issuing  Orders,"  Public  Management,  1945,  Vol.  27,  pp.  206-208,  contains 
much  wisdom  pertinent  to  the  subject. 


396  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

ticipant  in  a  particular  procedure.  It  shows  in  tabular  form  the  activities 
of  all  employees  and  the  time  they  spend  on  their  work.  The  process  chart 
or  flow  chart  traces  step-by-step  "what  happens"  for  a  given  procedure— 
what  is  done,  who  does  it,  time  consumed,  and  space  and  time  between 
each  step.  The  workload  chart  or  work  count  aims  to  answer  the  ques- 
tion of  "how  much."  What  is  counted  and  the  method  of  counting  depend 
upon  what  is  being  studied.  The  chart's  uses  are  in  dividing,  relating,  and 
scheduling  work;  finding  bottlenecks;  stimulating  competitive  interests  in 
performance;  assessing  personnel  needs;  and  appraising  the  value  of  parti- 
cular processes.  Using  these  three  tools  of  analysis  and  sometimes  others, 
work  simplification  programs  perform  the  function  of  modernizing  and 
streamlining  procedures. 

Procedure  standardization  differs  from  work  simplification  chiefly  in 
emphasis,  though  it  may  make  use  of  the  same  tools.  It  seeks  to  discover 
and  install  the  one  most  economical  and  efficient  procedure  for  doing 
common  or  interrelated  work  of  certain  kinds.  In  order  to  merit  a 
standardization  study,  an  operation  must  be  a  fairly  basic  one,  it  must 
cut  across  much  or  all  of  the  organization,  and  it  must  involve  a  reasonably 
large  number  of  persons.  The  values  of  procedure  standardization  lie  in 
such  matters  as  clarifying  policy  intent;  publicizing  and  generalizing  all 
useful  information  that  was  formerly  the  possession  of  a  few  employees; 
standardizing  costs  and  man-hour  requirements;  and  training  new  person- 
nel by  the  use  of  procedural  manuals. 

Problems  of  Procedure-Making.  The  central  problem  in  procedure- 
making  of  any  kind  is  how  to  combine  experience  in  procedure  per  se  with 
[knowledge  about  and  an  adequate  "feeling"  for  the  operations  which  par- 
ticular procedures  govern.  To  hard-working  operating  officials,  the  "proce- 
dural analyst"  may  seem  an  uninformed  busybody — he  cannot  possibly 
know  as  much  about  the  operation  as  those-on-the-job,  it's  none  of  his 
business  anyway,  and  if  he  really  wants  to  be  helpful — as  he  says  he  does! — 
let  him  pitch  in  and  help  with  the  work  that's  piling  up.  To  the  inquiring 
procedural  analyst,  in  turn,  operating  officials  may  seem  short-sighted,  self- 
centered,  narrow-minded — each  interested  only  in  his  task  of  the  moment 
and  utterly  lacking  in  organizational  perspective.  Failure  to  solve  satisfac- 
torily this  central  problem  of  combining  diverse  outlooks  has  two  results. 
Either  the  procedure-making  organ,  if  bolstered  by  formal  authority, 
promulgates  procedures  that  are  useless  and  often  disregarded;  or  no  pro- 
cedural changes  are  made  except  through  tedious  evolution  or  violent 
revolution. 

Let  it  be  admitted  that  the  task  of  the  procedural  analyst  is  frequently 
difficult  and  thankless.  Interest  in  procedures  is  a  rather  rare  and  precious 
quality,  likely  to  mark  him  as  suspect  at  the  outset.  Interference  with 
established  habits  evokes  deep  and  often  sharp  psychological  reactions. 
The  innate  aversion  to  change  is  often  reinforced  by  fear  of  loss  of  employ- 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  397 

ment  or  of  harder  work  if  the  status  quo  is  disturbed.  By  humorous  legend, 
the  "efficiency  expert"  is  peculiarly  liable  to  accidents,  such  as  falling  down 
an  elevator  shaft  or  into  an  acid  vat! 

On  the  other  hand,  let  it  also  be  admitted  that  the  Bright-Eyed  Young 
Chap  from  upstairs  is  frequently  a  sore  trial  to  any  one  who  has  already 
missed  the  deadline  on  his  current  assignment.  Much  is  still  to  be  done  in 
"humanizing"  the  procedural  analyst  and  in  helping  him  to  develop  suit- 
able protective  coloration.  And  after  all,  we  cannot  deny  the  kernel  of 
wisdom  in  the  belief  that  "there  is  much  to  be  said  for  a  poor  procedure 
if  people  are  used  to  it."  A  change  in  procedure  may  or  may  not  pay  off 
over  the  long  haul,  but  the  immediate  results,  as  the  man-on-the-job  knows, 
are  almost  certain  to  be  temporary  confusion,  unhappiness,  questioning, 
and  complaint. 

No  simple  solution  exists  to  this  central  problem  of  procedural  im- 
provement— the  proper  admixture  of  diverse  interests.  Two  devices  for 
helping  to  solve  it  are,  however,  being  used  with  increasing  success.  One 
is  the  employee-suggestion  system,  with  rewards  in  honor  or  money  to  those 
who  submit  practicable  suggestions  for  administrative  improvement.  "Sug- 
gestion boxes"  are  venerable  institutions,  but  the  potentialities  of  employee- 
suggestion  systems  for  a  number  of  important  purposes  are  receiving  grow- 
ing recognition.  The  other  device  is  the  work-simplification  program,  dis- 
cussed earlier,  which  depends  for  its  success  upon  training  supervisory  per- 
sonnel in  the  philosophy  and  basic  methods  of  procedural  analysis  and 
improvement.  There  is  nothing  esoteric  in  such  tools  as  the  process  chart. 
The  more  widespread  how-to-do-it-better  thinking  becomes,  the  closer  to 
solution  will  be  one  of  the  fundamental  problems  of  administration. 

Reference  has  been  made  in  our  discussion  to  "good"  procedure  as  dis- 
tinguished from  poor.  But  what  is  "good"  procedure?  Again,  no  simple 
answer  is  possible.  Or  rather,  a  simple  answer  is  possible  but  not  very 
helpful:  good  procedure  is  that  which  is  well  adapted  to  achieve  the  desired 
'ends.  The  trouble  arises  both  in  defining  the  "desired  ends"  and  in  de- 
termining whether  the  procedure  really  is  well  adapted  to  achieving  them 
once  they  have  been  agreed  upon. 

The  ends  sought  by  administration  are  not  easily  stated.  They  are  com- 
plex and  intangible,  and  it  is  often  difficult  to  determine  which  of  them  is 
to  be  served  by  a  procedure,  and  in  what  proportions.  After  decision  upon 
ends,  the  relative  "efficiency  and  economy"  of  alternative  procedures  must 
be  measured.  Efficiency  and  economy  are  not  readily  applied  criteria;  they 
vary  in  their  implications  according  to  the  goal  in  view.  Much  progress 
has  been  made  in  recent  years  in  achieving  objective  standards  of  measure- 
ment in  some  fields  of  administrative  performance.  However,  the  tools  are 
still  relatively  crude  and  inadequate.  Thus,  a  new  procedure  saves  paper  and 
filing  facilities;  yet  can  we  be  sure  that  the  operating  official  is  not  right 
when  he  says  that  the  saving  is  but  a  straw  in  the  balance  compared  to  the 


398  GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE 

objectives  served  by  more  complete  records?  Or  a  new  procedure  estab- 
lishes the  optimum  specialization  of  the  functions  of  three  clerks,  as  de- 
termined by  work  counts  and  time-and-motion  studies;  yet  can  we  be  sure 
that  staleness  and  increased  fatigue  will  not  outweigh  the  gain  within  a 
month?  Suppose  that  under  the  new  arrangement  the  three  clerks  are  not 
as  "happy"  as  before.  Is  the  happiness  of  employees  a  legitimate  considera- 
tion in  democratic  administration?  Even  on  a  practical  basis,  are  we  sure 
the  happiness  won't  "pay  off"  over  the  long  run  in  loyalty  and  morale? 
The  "grammar"  of  procedure — its  routine  steps  and  its  customary  tools — 
is  easy  to  learn.  But  knowledge  of  grammar  is  at  most  a  first  step  in  pro- 
ducing literature.  And  the  art  of  procedural  analysis  still  far  transcends 
the  science.8 

5.  How  TO  LIVE  AMONG  PROCEDURES 

Law  Versus  Dispatch.  In  the  stereotypes  that  the  political  cartoonist 
has  created,  the  public  bureaucrat  is  either  a  malignant  person  who  spins 
"red  tape"  to  accomplish  his  own  wicked  designs  or  a  stupid  person  who 
creates  red  tape  in  the  image  of  his  stupidity.9 

Some  of  the  reasons  why  these  stereotypes  have  found  such  widespread 
acceptance  should  now  be  clear.  In  the  management  of  its  internal  affairs, 
public  administration  is  for  political  reasons  bound  by  rules  designed  to 

8  Some  of  the  material  dealing  with  procedural  analysis  has  been  prepared  for  agency  use 
only;  some  material,  though  more  widely  circulated,  is  not  available  except  in  specialized 
libraries.  Generally,  and  especially  in  the  area  of  policy  procedures,  much  remains  to  be  done, 
both  in  exploration  and  publication  for  general  use.  Work  simplification  and  procedure 
standardization  stem  from  and  are  associated  with  the  scientific-management  movement.  They 
arc  direct  descendants  of  Frederick  Taylor's  early  searches  for  the  "one  best  way."  The  litera- 
ture of  this  field,  such  as  the  time  and  motion  studies  of  the  journal  Advanced  Management, 
should  be  consulted  on  various  aspects  of  these  subjects. 

See  also  Clascr,  Comstock,  Administrative  Procedure:  A  Practical  Handbook  for  the  Ad- 
ministrative Analyst,  especially  chs.  1,  5,  and  11,  Washington:  American  Council  on  Public 
Affairs,  1941;  Gottschalk,  Col.  Oliver  A.,  "Standardization  of  Procedure,"  Public  Administration 
Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  287-297;  Raising  Management's  Sights  on  Office  Organization 
(pamphlet),  New  York:  American  Management  Association,  1944;  Work  Simplification  (pam- 
phlet), reprinted  from  Adjutant -General's  School  Bulletin,  June  1943  issue.  Excellent  tech- 
nical material  may  be  found  in  the  following:  Manual  for  Control  Officers:  Volume  HI,  Work 
Simplification,  Washington:  Control  Division,  Headquarters,  Services  of  Supply,  1942;  Control 
Manual  (M703-7):  Simplification  and  Standardization  of  Procedures,  Washington:  Head- 
quarters, Army  Service  Forces,  1944;  Control  Manual  (M703-4):  Work  Simplification  (Material 
Handling),  Washington:  Headquarters,  Army  Service  Forces,  1943;  Control  Manual  (M703-6): 
Standardization  of  Forms,  Washington:  Headquarters,  Army  Service  Forces,  1944;  Work 
Simplification,  As  Exemplified  by  the  Work  Simplification  Program  of  the  U.  S.  Bureau  of  the 
Budget,  Publication  No.  91,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1945. 

A  very  good  picture  of  the  procedural  problems  and  apparatus  of  an  important  agency 
can  be  gained  by  studying  two  essays,  written  from  different  points  of  view,  about  the  War 
Production  Board:  Levinc,  David  D.,  "Administrative  Control  Techniques  of  the  War  Pro- 
duction Board,'*  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  pp.  89-96;  and  O'Brian,  John 
Lord  and  Flcischmann,  Manly,  "The  War  Production  Board  Administrative  Policies  and  Pro- 
cedures," George  Washington  Law  Review,  1944,  Vol.  13,  pp.  1-60. 

*  Cf.  also  above  Ch.  3,  "Bureaucracy — Fact  and  Fiction." 


GOVERNMENT  BY  PROCEDURE  399 

guarantee  complete  honesty  and  accountability,10  not  solely  efficiency  and 
economy  as  these  qualities  are  understood  in  private  affairs.  In  its  regu- 
latory activities,  public  administration  is  governed  by  legal  rules  and  insti- 
tutions evolved  over  a  long  period  of  time  to  guarantee  the  rights  of  the 
citizen  against  unwarranted  governmental  interference.  Certainly  we  can- 
not expect  particular  speed  and  dispatch  of  public  administration  when  it 
is  subject  to  a  body  of  law  designed  to  prevent  too  great  speed  and  dispatch. 
Perhaps  speed  and  dispatch  need  more  emphasis  as  against  guarantees  of 
rights.  Or  perhaps  under  modern  conditions  rights  can  be  better  guaran- 
teed with  more  speed  and  dispatch  in  the  public's  affairs.  But  let  the  issues 
be  clear. 

Deficient  Procedures.  It  must  be  conceded,  of  course,  that  some  admin- 
istrative procedures  fall  far  short  of  legitimate  aspirations.  Such  instances 
usually  occur  because  a  procedure,  once  satisfactory,  no  longer  fits  the  facts. 
Procedures  are  habits,  and  habits  notoriously  persist  into  senility  after  the 
rational  faculties  have  been  blunted.  It  is  seldom,  however,  that  public 
procedures  reflect  mere  personal  ends;  the  preventive  checks  are  too  certain. 
The  contrary  belief  stems  rather  from  the  prior  and  more  fundamental 
matter  of  disagreement  with  an  agency's  objectives. 

Assessing  Red  Tape.  One  whose  blood-pressure  rises  dangerously  upon 
encountering  "red  tape"  in  public  administration  can  with  therapeutic 
benefits  pursue  several  lines  of  thought.  He  can  reflect  upon  the  wisdom 
of  General  Marshall's  dictum  that  "if  you  cut  red  tape  you  must  be  damn 
sure  of  what  you  are  doing."  After  all,  one  man's  red  tape  is  another  man's 
system.  Only  when  all  the  facts  are  known  can  condemnation  be  fairly 
entered  and  a  change  be  recommended  that  is  likely  to  be  beneficial.  Rarely 
does  an  isolated  encounter  with  a  personally  irritating  procedure  yield  the 
knowledge  necessary  for  a  just  condemnation.  Or  he  can  reflect  that  red 
tape  constitutes  a  protection  against  precipitate  and  arbitrary  official  action 
to  his  detriment,  and  that  this  must  be  weighed  against  any  possible  annoy- 
ance in  dealing  with  government.  Or  he  may  elect  to  act  upon  the  half- 
truth  that  red  tape,  like  caries  or  cancer,  is  an  affliction  of  civilization,  and 
Thoreau-like  retreat  to  his  own  Walden  Pond. 

Those  inside  the  organization  will  also  find  these  remedies  generally 
applicable  for  their  own  irritations.  Indeed,  irritation  with  an  agency's 
red  tape  is  a  chronic  and  often  acute  complaint  of  public  employees.  Of 
course,  it  is  usually  the  other  fellow's  red  tape  that  is  at  fault;  and  since  he 
is  a  member  of  the  same  staff  he  can  be  hated  with  the  special  fierceness 
that  characterizes  fratricidal  strife.  What  is  more  important,  the  govern- 
ment employee  should  recognize  that  he  is  in  no  event  bound  to  be  a  mere 
pawn  in  the  game.  No  matter  how  lowly  his  status,  he  has  both  a  right 
and  an  obligation  to  seek  to  improve  procedures. 

10  Cf.  below  Part  IV,  "Responsibility  and  Accountability." 


CHAPTER 

18 

The  Tasks  of  Middle  Management 

1.   THE  DUAL  FUNCTION  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

Importance  of  Intermediate  Points  of  Control.  In  order  to  bring  execu- 
tive direction  to  bear  upon  the  general  flow  of  operations  in  which  the  end 
product  of  public  service  takes  its  shape,  administrative  agencies — like  all 
large-scale  enterprise — resort  to  hierarchical  organization.1  The  essential 
function  of  hierarchy  is  to  provide  an  integrated  scheme  of  intermediate 
control  points  for  the  attainment  of  efficiency,  consistency,  and  continuity  of 
cooperative  effort.  In  linking  these  control  points  in  descending  order,  from 
the  head  of  the  organization  to  progressively  lower  subordinates  down  to 
the  first-line  supervisor,  we  arrive  at  a  "chain  of  command." 

Too  often  we  speak  of  hierarchy  as  if  it  were  a  physical  structure  sep- 
arate from  the  human  element.  Actually  it  is  more  in  the  nature  of  a  tex- 
ture of  relationships — each  member  of  the  hierarchy  responding  to  his 
superior  and  in  turn  influencing  his  subordinates,  with  countless  variables 
of  relationship  entering  into  the  picture.2  Nor  must  it  be  assumed  that 
hierarchy  is  principally  a  device  for  superimposing  top  determinations  upon 
the  whole  organization.  Hierarchy  does  engender  a  desirable  centripetal 
pull,  preventing  the  cooperative  undertaking  from  falling  apart.  However, 
the  chief  test  of  its  effectiveness  lies  in  appropriate  devolution  of  respon- 
sibility so  as  to  allow  the  organization  to  work  under  its  own  "steam."  To 
the  same  degree  that  hierarchy  reinforces  accountability  and  responsiveness 
toward  the  top,  it  should  also  relieve  those  at  the  top  of  unnecessary  burdens. 
This  can  be  done  only  by  adequate  delegation  of  authority.  Devolution  of 
responsibility  without  commensurate  delegation  of  authority  is  an  empty 
gesture,  bound  to  lead  nowhere. 

Small-scale  organization  has  only  two  vulnerable  areas — the  character 
of  its  leadership  and  the  productivity  of  its  immediate  operators.  In  large- 

1  Sec  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  of  Organization/'  sec.  3,  "Quest  of  Organizational 
Unity." 

2  See  above  Ch.  13,  "Informal  Organization.'* 

400 


THE  TASKS  OF   MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  401 

scale  organization,  the  number  of  vulnerable  areas  is  much  greater  because 
of  the  multitude  of  intermediate  control  points  between  top  management 
and  the  rank  and  file  of  employees.  iys_therefw^lwj;dy^an ^exaggeration  to 
sa^jhat^one  of  the  most  critical_sectors  of  management  in  large-scale  or- 
ganizations lies  in  the  intermediate  ranges  of  cpmmand.  The  whole  con- 
cept of  "channels  of  command"  underscores  the  importance  of  those  points 
of  internal  control  and  direction  which  are  lodged  between  the  responsible 
head  of  the  organization  and  his  working  force  at  the  base  of  operations. 
The  total  distribution  of  these  intermediate  points  of  control  and  direction 
indicates  the  field  of  middle  management. 

Middle  Management — Stepchild  of  Administrative  Research.  Consider- 
ing the  significance  of  middle  management  for  the  success  of  any  large-scale 
organization,  it  is  surprising  to  notice  how  little  emphasis  it  has  found  in 
the  literature  on  administration,  both  public  and  private.  A  good  deal  of 
attention  has  been  devoted  to  the  functions  of  the  chief  executive3  and  to  his 
staff  facilities.4  Much  the  same  is  true  of  administrative  leadership  on  the 
departmental  level.5  In  large  measure  the  explanation  for  the  relative  fail- 
ure to  deal  more  explicitly  with  the  particular  problems  surrounding  middle 
management  must  be  sought  in  two  historic  factors. 

In  the  first  place,  the  movement  toward  administrative  reform  since 
early  in  the  century  logically  saw  its  main  goal  in  the  institutional  invig- 
oration  of  the  chief  executive.  In  stressing  his  responsibility  for  the  entire 
executive  branch,  the  reform  movement  chose  the  most  promising  lever  for 
achieving  better  management  throughout  the  administrative  structure. 
Beginning  with  the  novel  concept  of  a  budget  office  attached  to  the  chief 
executive,  his  "arms  of  management"  were  consciously  designed  to  make 
responsible  direction  truly  effective.  Because  of  the  traditional  intransigence- 
of  the  line  departments,  the  new  establishments  with  government-wide  con- 
cerns were  generally  entrusted  with  extensive  control  functions—quite  in 
harmony  with  the  precedent  of  civil  service  commissions. 

Exercise  of  such  technical  controls  called  for  personnel  of  professional 
competence  to  carry  out  specialized  assignments.  As  a  consequence,  the 
particular  knowledge  and  training  required  to  build  and  sustain  staff  or 
auxiliary  services  have  been  in  the  forefront  of  academic  and  practical  in- 
terest, deflecting  consideration  from  the  no  less  important  needs  of  middle 
management.  Judging  only  by  the  dominant  currents  running  through 
the  great  bulk  of  administrative  research  and  writings,  we  might  easily  be 
led  to  the  inference  that  middle  managers  are  a  mentally  inert  mass,  stung 
into  action  solely  by  the  indefatigable  prodding  of  shock  brigades  of  special- 

3  See  above  Ch.  8,  "The  Chief  Executive." 

4  See  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  o£  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Line  and  Staff";  Ch.  8, 
"The  Chief  Executive,"  sec.  5,  "Arms  of  Modern  Management";  Ch.  9,  "The  Departmental 
System,"  sec.  2;  "Interdepartmental  Coordination." 

5  See  above  Ch.  9,  "The  Departmental  System,"  sec.  3,  "The  Secretary's  Business." 


402  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

ists  descending  upon  them  from  the  higher  realm  of  knowledge— admin- 
istrative planning,  budgeting,  organization  and  methods  analysis,  and 
personnel  work. 

The  second  historic  factor  that  has  contributed  to  the  relative  neglect  of 
middle  management  is  related  to  the  first.  It  is  the  lack  of  homogeneity 
and  cohesiveness  of  middle  management  as  an  occupational  grouping.  Most 
of  the  staff  and  auxiliary  services  have  developed  into  fairly  well-defined 
careers,  each  distinguished  by  marked  characteristics.  A  training  specialist, 
for  instance,  is  readily  identified  by  his  specialization.  There  is  no  such 
distinct  career  in  middle  management.  Broadly  speaking,  middle  man- 
agers are  the  natural  offspring  of  a  vast  variety  of  functions  and  subfunc- 
tions  proliferating  all  over  the  administrative  scene.  These  functions  and 
subfunctions,  not  the  essence  of  middle  management  itself,  are  the  areas 
of  their  specialized  competence.  Ordinarily  they  are  middle  managers  not 
because  they  have  displayed  specific  managerial  talent  as  such,  but  because 
they  have  shown  ability  in  the  context  of  a  particular  function  or  subfunc- 
tion  administered  by  their  agency. 

Recognition  of  a  Higher  Line  Career.  In  1941,  the  President's  Com- 
mittee on  Civil  Service  Improvement,  under  the  chairmanship  of  Justice 
Reed,  pointed  out  that  middle  management,  though  identified  as  such 
through  the  common  character  of  its  responsibilities,  had  no  standing  as  a 
specific  category  within  the  federal  service  for  purposes  of  systematic  train- 
ing and  selection.  Focusing  especially  on  the  higher  middle  and  top  grades 
of  the  classified  service,  the  committee  observed  that  these  officials  "perform 
the  most  difficult  and  responsible  office  work  along  specialized  lines  re- 
quiring extended  training  and  experience."6  As  the  committee  put  it,7 
those  occupying  such  advanced  permanent  positions: 

.  .  .  perform  the  function  of  overhead  management,  direction,  and 
supervision  in  every  branch  of  the  Federal  Government.  This  is  the 
principal  duty  of  bureau  chiefs  and  assistant  bureau  chiefs,  of  directors 
of  divisions  and  assistant  directors,  of  heads  of  institutions,  of  the  execu- 
tive officers  of  commissions  and  their  associates,  and  of  a  growing  num- 
ber of  administrative  assistants  and  assistants  to  executives  in  high  posi- 
tion. It  is  also  one  of  the  duties  of  the  President  and  heads  of  departments 
and  agencies,  secretaries,  commissioners,  administrators  and  others;  but 
these  high  officials  have  policy-determining  duties  and  political  respon- 
sibilities as  well,  which  are  absent  from  the  permanent  branch  of  admin- 
istration. In  its  elementary  forms  the  same  function  may  be  said  to  reach 
down  to  the  first-line  supervisors  who  must  plan,  direct,  and  coordinate 
the  work  of  the  rank  and  file. 

While  the  Reed  Committee  did  not  differentiate  sharply  between  staff 
and  line  positions,  dealing  rather  with  the  more  advanced  classified  grades 

*  President's  Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improvement,  Report,  p.  56,  House  Doc.  No.  118, 
77th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1941. 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  403 

in  general,  it  necessarily  included  in  its  inquiry  the  main  body  of  middle 
managers.  The  committee  felt  that  better  awareness  of  the  distinctive  re- 
quirements of  these  grades,  especially  from  the  point  of  view  of  selection  and 
preparation,  would  yield  measurable  profit.  Summarizing  its  recommenda- 
tions, it  stated:8 

In  general  terms,  we  think  it  would  be  helpful  if  the  positions  involv- 
ing administrative  duties  were  identified  and  carefully  described  in  each 
department  and  agency,  and  if  each  department  and  agency  made  and 
kept  current  a  list  or  inventory  of  persons  who  had  demonstrated  that 
they  possessed  administrative  skill,  with  the  personal  and  official  history, 
present  classification  and  other  relevant  data.  We  also  believe  that  the 
continuous  search  for  good  prospective  material  for  administration 
should  be  more  definitely  recognized  in  some  departments  and  agencies 
as  a  joint  responsibility  of  supervisors  and  personnel  officers.  Finally, 
we  think  that  the  machinery  is  now  for  the  first  time  available  to  permit 
a  desirable  extension  of  the  program  of  training  and  testing  which  is 
already  in  operation  in  most  departments. 

No  doubt  a  more  methodical  approach  would  go  far  toward  promoting 
the  characteristic  qualifications  called  for  in  administrative  work,  especially 
that  of  middle  management.  This  is  not  merely  a  matter  of  enhanced 
competence.  It  also  carries  over  into  the  general  orientation  and  the  op- 
erational outlook  of  middle  managers.  Hence  the  Reed  Committee  quite 
properly  concerned  itself  with  the  broader  question  of  occupational  attitudes. 
What  it  had  to  say  on  this  point  could  hardly  occasion  surprise.  In  its 
own  language:9 

Government  departments  and  agencies,  their  divisions  and  their  sub- 

•  divisions,  suffer  from  an  insularity  which  hampers  their  effective  coordi- 

'  nation  as  parts  of  a  single  whole.    Indifference,  jealously,  competition, 

I  and  sometimes  even  sabotage  develop  in  the  effort  of  each  small  unit  to 

protect  itself  and  its  staff.   There  is  too  little  recognition  of  a  common 

responsibility  to  a  common  and  single  employer,  the  American  people 

as  represented  by  the  Congress  and  the  President. 

Such  insularity  is  in  part  the  result  of  both  the  size  and  the  functionali- 
zation  of  large-scale  organization.  Tied  to  a  particular  subdivision  in  a 
complex  structure  of  vast  dimensions,  the  middle  manager  is  apt  to  identify 
himself  with  the  more  tangible  realities  and  objectives  of  his  subdivision. 
In  part,  however,  his  insular  point  of  view  derives  from  the  fact  that  under 
existing  conditions  he  has  difficulty  in  seeing  himself  as  part  of  a  profession 
different  from  the  particular  function  within  which  he  rose.  Lack  of  a 
uniting  bond  among  the  exponents  of  middle  management  keeps  him  en- 
slaved to  the  individual  function  in  which  he  has  his  roots.  Recognition 
of  middle  management  in  terms  of  a  career  grouping  would  tend  to  draw 
its  mentality  from  the  particular  to  the  general,  away  from  the  specialized 


p.  57.     See  also  above  Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  3, 
"Training  for  Public  Administration." 
.  D.  61. 


404  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

functional  activities  from  which  it  springs.  Career  integration  would 
deepen  the  middle  manager's  consciousness  of  his  general  role,  especially 
if  reinforced  by  a  government-wide  scheme  of  interfunctional  and  inter- 
departmental transfers  within  the  entire  administrative  group.  He  thus 
would  gain  wider  vision  and  greater  capacity  for  coordinative  adjustments. 

For  this  reason,  it  may  be  doubted  whether  the  Reed  Committee's  re- 
luctance to  propose  a  consolidated  higher  administrative  service  was  really 
in  line  with  the  general  run  of  its  own  recommendations.  A  higher  ad- 
ministrative career  marked  out  as  such  would  at  the  same  time  furnish 
much-needed  opportunities  for  a  freer  interchange  of  personnel  between 
staff  and  line  positions.  It  may  still  be  the  most  effective  device  for  bridging 
the  gulf  between  these  two  elements— a  gulf  that  interferes  seriously 
with  the  intimacy  of  give-and-take  that  is  required  for  sound  staff-line 
relationships. 

Middle  Management  and  Top  Direction.  Good  staff  work  implies  not 
only  mastery  of  pertinent  fields  of  knowledge  but  also  a  high  degree  of 
sensitivity  to  the  needs  of  the  top  executive  and  to  the  problems  that  are  on 
the  minds  of  line  officials.  In  much  the  same  way,  effective  middle  manage- 
ment, aside  from  intellectual  command  of  the  functional  specialization  in 
which  it  operates,  requires  receptivity  to  higher  executive  direction  as  well 
as  capacity  for  team  leadership.  The  outstanding  factor  about  top-level 
direction  is  that  it  must  encompass  the  organization  as  a  whole  and  deal 
with  each  issue  in  terms  of  the  whole.  As  the  principal  support  of  top-level 
direction,  middle  management  therefore  has  to  show  itself  able  to  infuse 
the  generality  of  organization-wide  purposes  into  its  individual  operations. 
On  this  score  it  can  succeed  only  insofar  as  it  captures  in  its  own  thinking 
the  broad-range  ends  of  the  organization  at  large.  Conversely,  it  is  bound 
to  fail  in  exact  proportion  to  the  insularity  of  its  outlook. 

If  the  middle  manager  proves  incapable  of  reenacting  in  his  own  prov- 
ince the  generality  of  organizational  ends,  of  relating  his  day-by-day  actions 
to  the  total  administrative  process,  he  in  effect  defaults  on  his  basic  duty. 
More  mindful  of  his  immediate  sphere,  he  becomes  a  counterinfluence  to 
higher  executive  direction  rather  than  its  elongation.  For  all  practical  pur- 
poses he  partially  checkmates  top  management,  denying  it  full  scope  over 
the  organization  and  making  himself  a  victual -vassal  who  grants  or  with- 
holds his  support  as  convenience,  expediency,  or  special  inducements  might 
indicate.  Under  such  conditions  the  middle  manager  is  not  far  from  ar- 
rogating to  himself  all  management  in  his  orbit,  defying,  obstructing,  or 
yielding  to  demands  from  above  only  as  he  sees  fit,  however  well  he  may 
choose  to  disguise  his  actual  autonomy.  This  may  be  deliberate  in  certain  in- 
stances, especially  when  a  middle  manager  is  at  odds  with  the  higher  powers 
and  is  also  protected  by  a  more  or  less  concealed  alliance  with  political  or 
economic  groups  outside  the  organization.10  As  a  rule  he  succumbs  to 

above  Ch.  13,  "Informal  Organization/'  sec.  2,  "Elements  of  Informal  Organization.*' 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  405 

such  autonomistic  tendencies  unconsciously.  Top  management  is  far  away. 
It  is  referred  to  not  as  "we"  but  as  "they"— "we"  do  things  our  own  way; 
"they"  come  in  to  tell  us,  though  having  not  the  faintest  idea  of  "our" 
troubles  and  "our"  business. 

The  strength  of  middle  management  rests  in  the  fact  that  it  thoroughly 
knows  its  own  "shop."  This  knowledge  is  the  middle  manager's  stock-in- 
trade  and  his  legitimate  pride.  Staff  specialists  are  likely  to  be  glared  at 
with  particular  fierceness  when  they  are  tactless  enough  to  demonstrate 
that  through  their  own  analysis  they  have  come  to  know  the  "shop"  as  well, 
if  not  better.  Operators  naturally  do  not  take  too  well  to  the  idea  that  any 
one  might  know  as  much  about  operations  as  they  do.  However,  the  virtue 
of  the  middle  manager's  intimate  familiarity  with  his  own  segment  of  the 
organization  has  its  corresponding  vice.  The  vice  of  the  virtue  lies  in  a 
proportionately  dimmer  perception  of  what  the  organization  is  trying  to  ac- 
complish as  a  whole.  Such  dimmed  perception  inevitably  affects  the  role 
of  middle  management  as  an  elongation  of  the  executive  function. 

However  urgent  and  continuous  its  attention  to  the  progress  of  opera- 
tions, middle  management  must  find  as  much  time  as  it  can  to  face  upward, 
As  an  informed  student  of  administration  has  expressed  it,  "the  drag  of 
inadequacy  is  always  downward.  The  need  in  administration  is  always 
for  the  reverse:  for  a  secretary  to  project  his  thinking  to  the  governmental 
level,  for  a  bureau  chief  to  try  to  see  the  problems  of  the  department,  for 
the  division  chief  to  comprehend  the  work  of  the  entire  bureau."11  Nc 
doubt  one  of  the  most  pressing  needs  in  administration  is  that  for  increas- 
ingly more  comprehensive  consideration  as  matters  move  upward  from  the 
bottom  to  the  top.  However,  such  progressive  generalization  in  the  pres- 
entation of  each  individual  subject  that  calls  for  higher  action  does  not 
come  forth  of  its  own.  Top  management,  expecting  support  from  the 
middle  manager,  must  extend  its  hand  to  him,  so  to  speak.  It  must  ac- 
tively seek  to  convey  to  him  a  sense  of  organization-wide  objectives.  Effec- 
tive communication  of  top-level  policy  is  one  method  of  achieving  this  end. 
Another  is  untiring  demonstration  of  the  interest  that  top  management  has 
in  the  way  operations  are  going. 

The  institutional  communication  system  is  therefore  a  matter  of  crucial 
significance  for  the  entire  conduct  of  middle  management.12  A  top  man- 
agement that  wraps  itself  in  silence  resembles  a  head  after  decapitation. 
Top-level  action  by  itself  is  an  entirely  insufficient  agent  of  communication. 
In  the  first  place,  such  action  is  by  no  means  always  conspicuous  through- 
out the  organization.  In  many  instances  the  determination  and  adjustment 
of  policy  in  the  highest  councils  of  the  organization  aim  at  longer-range 

11  Applcby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  p.  45,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945.  See  also  above  Ch.  9, 
"The  Departmental  System,"  sec.  4,  "The  Bureau  Pattern." 

12  See  also  above  Ch.   16,  "The  Formulation  of  Administrative  Policy,"  sec.  1,  "Policy 
Formation  and  Policy  Sanction.*' 


406  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

effects  rather  than  immediately  visible  changes.  The  large  body  of  person- 
nel in  the  organization  may  live  through  many  a  day  before  the  first  con- 
crete ripples  of  the  change  come  down  to  it.  Secondly,  the  bare  policy 
pronouncement  and  the  letter  of  administrative  orders  and  instructions  are 
too  frugal  a  diet  to  nurture  full  understanding  of  institutional  goals.  For 
their  own  purposes,  middle  managers  need  to  know  the  motivations,  in- 
tentions, and  reasons  that  go  into  directives  handed  down  to  them. 

Without  being  adequately  posted  on  the  course  steered  by  top  manage- 
ment, middle  managers  are  likely  to  lose  themselves  in  the  particular 
transactions  for  which  they  are  responsible.  In  the  absence  of  an  elucida- 
tion of  general  ends,  smaller  problems  assert  themselves — magnified  to  the 
point  of  distortion.  The  result  is  functional  isolation  and  separatism — the 
occupational  diseases  of  large-scale  enterprise.  At  the  same  time,  ignorance 
of  top-level  objectives  encourages  middle  managers  to  allow  matters  that 
with  better  knowledge  could  be  settled  by  them  on  the  spot  to  pass  on  to  the 
higher  superior,  causing  dangerous  congestion  in  the  upper  ranges  of  the 
organization.  This  inclination  in  turn  decreases  the  middle  manager's  op- 
portunity for  creative  self-application.  It  is  thus  clear  that  inadequate 
downward  communication  in  large  part  cancels  out  the  fundamental  con- 
tribution which  middle  management  is  designed  to  make  in  giving  positive 
effect  to  top  direction. 

Middle  Management  and  Control  of  Operations.  At  the  base  of  ad- 
ministrative operations,  the  total  managerial  effort  concentrates  itself  in  the 
first-line  supervisor.  In  a  sense,  he  is  the  lowest  extension  of  middle 
management  in  the  hierarchical  structure.  Working  with  his  small  crew 
of  usually  no  more  than  ten  employees,  he  functions  very  much  like  the 
foreman  in  industry — organizing  his  team,  maintaining  the  pace  of  work, 
securing  the  necessary  quality  of  output,  developing  the  skill  of  those  work- 
ing for  him,  showing  them  how  to  do  their  job  and  how  to  do  it  better. 
If  we  think  of  middle  management  as  the  integrated  scheme  of  intermediate 
control  points  between  the  top  and  the  bottom  of  the  organization,  we  may 
regard  the  first-line  supervisor  as  being  outside  the  range  of  middle  man- 
agement. Supervision  on  his  level  will  be  treated  more  specifically  in 
another  chapter.13  However,  in  a  more  general  sense  supervision  runs 
through  the  entire  organization,  each  superior  supervising  his  immediate 
subordinates. 

By  and  large,  supervision  becomes  more  direct  as  we  proceed  downward 
in  the  hierarchy.  At  the  top,  it  tends  to  be  rather  general,  in  part  because 
of  the  plausible  assumption  of  higher  competence  for  independent  work  in 
the  upper  reaches  of  administrative  responsibility,  in  part  because  the  nature 
of  directive  activity — predominant  on  these  levels — renders  specific  sur- 
veillance unfeasible  and  ineffectual.  Here  the  record  of  achievement  or 
failure  must  be  extensively  relied  upon  as  a  substitute  for  the  eyes  of  the 

13  See  below  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision." 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  407 

supervisor.  In  the  lower  strata  of  the  organization,  supervision  is  apt  to  be 
closer  as  it  increasingly  relates  to  more  repetitive  and  less  complex  trans- 
actions. The  burdens  of  direct  supervision — typical  of  middle  management 
in  general — therefore  increase  from  level  to  level  as  the  distance  to  the  base 
of  operations  grows  shorter. 

Control  of  operations,  even  under  exceptionally  favorable  circumstances, 
is  never  a  purely  mechanical  process.  Human  beings  do  not  function  like 
machines.  Attainment  of  a  reasonably  standardized  group  product  hence 
requires  considerable  leeway  in  direction.  A  great  number  of  factors  enter 
into  any  kind  of  organized  group  action.  Only  when  the  middle  manager 
is  placed  in  a  position  to  influence  these  factors  without  undue  restraint  can 
he  be  expected  to  live  up  to  his  task.  It  follows  that  appropriate  delegation 
of  authority  is  a  basic  condition  to  successful  guidance  of  operations. 

Most  middle  managers  feel  that  the  scope  of  their  authority  is  inadequate 
to  their  responsibility.  How  much  justification  there  is  for  these  complaints 
we  shall  examine  in  a  subsequent  section.  Here  it  may  suffice  to  observe 
that  nowhere  is  the  urge  to  "be  left  alone"  as  great  as  in  the  line  cadres. 
This  is  not  surprising.  Face  to  face  with  the  task  to  "get  the  job  done," 
under  continuous  pressure  from  above  for  speed  and  action,  and  hungry 
for  the  emotional  thrill  of  "getting  results,"  the  middle  manager  is  prone 
to  wish  for  more  power  to  his  elbow.  His  eyes  focus  only  on  a  defined 
sector  of  operations,  only  on  part  of  the  organization.  But  within  that 
sector  he  is  supreme,  or  has  reason  to  think  of  himself  as  supreme.  And  he 
longs  for  the  totality  of  authority  that  would  make  him  fully  master. 

However  small,  this  is  his  world.  To  him,  it  is  a  complete  world,  just 
as  complete  in  itself  as  the  job  to  be  done.  Here  he  is  the  boss;  it  is  he 
who  is  answerable  for  the  state  of  business  in  his  sector;  it  is  he  who  earns 
the  credit  for  accomplishment.  The  head  of  his  agency  and  the  galaxy  of  staff 
people  higher  up  may  fancy  themselves  to  throne  above  the  whole  organi- 
zation and  deal  with  it  in  its  entirety.  However,  only  the  line  operator 
"hears  the  thing  tick."  Only  he  sees  the  concrete  product  of  operations. 
Only  he  has  the  satisfaction  of  visibly  carrying  his  forces  forward — through 
his  leadership,  his  grasp  of  the  situation,  and  what  he  personally  is  able 
to  do  about  the  situation.  Looking  for  drama  in  administration?  You 
find  it  most  easily  in  the  line. 

A  lot  has  been  said  about  managerial  "know  how"  of  late.  "Know 
how" — as  contrasted  with  the  theoretical  exposition  of  the  executive  func- 
tion or  an  understanding  of  the  techniques  of  administrative  analysis, 
budgeting,  and  personnel  administration — is  for  the  most  part  the  property 
of  middle  management.  "Know  how"  arises  principally  from  trying- 
shrewd  experimentation,  ingenious  improvisation,  swift  adjustment,  and 
that  kind  of  resilient  initiative  which  is  always  willing  to  try  all  over  again. 
Much  of  the  glory  of  "know  how"  is  the  middle  manager's.  He  is  the  one 
who  performs  the  feat  of  bringing  together  the  manpower  and  the  tools 


408  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE   MANAGEMENT 

allowed  him  by  his  budget  so  that  tangible  values  of  public  service  come 
forth.  He  consolidates  the  human  relationships  into  purposeful  and  pro- 
ductive effort.  He  also  feels  the  first  repercussions  of  lowered  morale,  and 
is  the  first  called  into  the  breach  to  furnish  personal  inspiration  in  order 
to  raise  the  spirit  of  his  force.  *"' 

Control  of  operations  extends  all  the  way  from  the  planning  stage  to 
the  completion  point.  It  entails  the  programming  of  activities  to  meet 
specified  goals;  the  scheduling  of  step  sequences  in  order  to  relate  the  de- 
ployment of  personnel  to  the  time  factor;  the  spelling-out  of  particular 
assignments;  the  definition  of  standards  of  performance;  the  establishment 
of  recording  and  reporting  requirements;  the  designation  of  the  most  ap- 
propriate methods  and  techniques;  the  determination  of  the  most  expe- 
ditious flow  of  work;  the  identification  of  the  mechanics  used  for  checking 
progress  and  quality;  and  the  review  of  the  end  product.  Usually  all  of 
these  elements  blend  into  one  another.  Yet  each  has  its  part  to  play  in 
middle  management,  and  each  may  require  much  thought  and  great  care, 
especially  when  novel  functions  or  undertakings  are  involved  for  which 
past  experience  does  not  provide  a  dependable  guide.  In  such  instances, 
the  resourcefulness  of  line  officials  will  often  be  put  to  an  exacting  test. 

In  its  control  of  operations,  middle  management — to  use  a  military 
simile — is  in  the  main  concerned  with  the  tactics  of  administration,  leaving 
the  final  decisions  of  a  strategic  character  to  the  top  level  of  the  organization. 
The  middle  manager's  tactical  responsibilities  compel  him  to  face  downward, 
toward  the  detailed  transactions  at  the  base  of  the  hierarchical  structure. 
At  the  same  time,  as  we  have  noted  earlier,  he  must  view  himself  as  the 
internal  agent  of  top  management,  as  a  manifestation  of  the  executive  func- 
tion. This  makes  it  necessary  for  him  simultaneously  to  look  for  the  signals 
from  above.  In  a  very  real  sense,  therefore,  his  attention  is  persistently 
drawn  in  two  opposite  directions.  As  there  are  pressures  on  him  from  the 
top,  so  there  are  pressures  from  the  bottom.  The  impact  of  these  opposite 
pressures  would  tax  any  man's  equanimity.  It  is  thus  not  startling  that 
middle  managers  frequently  give  the  impression  of  being  either  hardboiled 
or  militantly  defensive.  They  can  hardly  help  it.  Theirs  is  a  tough  job 
that  favors  toughness  of  fiber. 

2.  SUPPORTING  TOP  DIRECTION 

Effectiveness  of  Downward  Communication.  In  order  to  achieve  a 
secure  alignment  with  middle  management,  top  direction  must  "explain 
itself"  as  fully  as  it  can.  As  has  already  been  suggested,  this  puts  in  bold 
relief  the  need  for  effective  downward  communication.  Communication 
has  two  separable  though  interrelated  aspects— content  and  form.  The  for- 
mer reaches  into  such  matters  as  volume  and  frequency.  The  latter  includes 
the  entire  process  of  communication. 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE   MANAGEMENT  409 

On  the  aspect  of  content,  it  would  be  trite  indeed  to  demand  clarity 
and  conciseness.  The  trouble  is  that  unprecise,  cryptic,  or  fragmentary  com- 
munication of  top-level  objectives  and  policies  in  many  cases  is  not  simply 
the  result  of  casualness,  inattention,  or  sloppy  phrasing.  The  head  of  an 
agency  and  his  intimate  associates  may  be  quite  clear  about  particular  ends 
and  yet  hesitate  greatly  to  make  these  ends  a  subject  of  organization-wide 
pronouncement.  The  matter  may  be  delicate;  it  may  imply  an  admission  of 
partial  failure;  it  may  require  the  equivalent  of  talking  "among  ourselves" 
in  the  family  circle. 

Large-scale  organization  meets  peculiar  limitations  on  this  score.  Its  size 
increases  the  chance  of  unwelcome  leakages.  With  so  many  people  involved 
in  the  echelons  of  middle  management  alone — quite  aside  from  the  still 
larger  body  of  first-line  supervisors — can  the  executive  be  sure  of  confiden- 
tial treatment?  Can  he  safely  assume  a  sufficient  degree  of  loyalty  every- 
where? Is  it  at  least  possible  to  take  for  granted  sympathetic  appreciation 
of  the  difficulties  he  confronts  in  striving  for  sensible  solutions,  especially 
when  these  must  reflect  a  high  degree  of  generality? 

Here,  then,  is  one  of  the  fundamental  reasons  why  downward  communi- 
cation so  often  seems  to  withhold  as  much  as  it  conveys.  It  throws  a  sharp 
light  on  the  importance  of  widespread  personal  identification  with  the  aims 
of  the  organization.  No  agency  can  think  or  talk  within  its  "four  walls" 
when  its  personnel  lacks  what  is  perhaps  best  termed  "sense  of  institution." 
This  is  not  to  minimize  the  stimulating  effect  of  constructive  argument  over 
differences  of  opinion.14  However,  only  high  esprit  dc  corps  can  provide 
the  general  climate  of  institutional  loyalty  that  would  permit  creative  dis- 
agreement within  the  frame  of  common  allegiance.15 

To  that  extent,  communication  is  predetermined  in  its  character  by  a 
firmly  implanted  service  ideology — an  area  thus  far  largely  unexplored 
despite  its  pivotal  significance.  What  little  discussion  of  service  ideology 
has  taken  place  points  for  the  most  part  to  the  possibility  of  self-protective 
solidarities — the  perils  of  "bureaucracy."  In  all  large-scale  enterprise,  the 
first  requirement  is  to  raise  the  individual's  mind  from  his  personal  predi- 
lections and  ambitions  to  the  plane  of  self-identification  with  the  coopera- 
tive effort.  It  is  a  secondary  proposition  to  guard  him  against  becoming  a 
mindless  serf  of  his  organizatiton. 

Downward  communication  may  be  a  meager  trickle  from  sheer  timidity; 
if  it  is,  the  fault  usually  lies  in  limp  leadership  at  the  top — leadership  that 
fails  to  arouse  enthusiasm  and  devotion  in  both  the  officialdom  and  the 
working  force  at  large.  Yet  downward  communication  may  also  suffer  from 

14  For  the  special  problems  that  under  auspices  of  interest  representation  affect  the  de- 
sirable administrative  "freedom  of  thought,"  see  above  Ch.  14,  "Interest  Groups  in  Administra- 
tion," sec.  3,  "Staffing  for  Point  of  View." 

15  On  this  question,  see  also  above  Ch.  13,  "Informal  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Elements 
of  Informal  Organization." 


410  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

an  entirely  different  ill— namely,  torrential  abundance.  This  is  also  often 
a  repercussion  of  weak  top  leadership.  The  policy  announcement  is  followed 
by  an  interminable  series  of  policy  clarifications.  Or  the  administrative  order 
carries  in  its  wake  a  whole  string  of  implementing  instructions,  one  more 
detailed  than  the  other.  The  essential  economy  of  communication  is  between 
these  two  extremes.  But  is  there  enough  concentration  on  atttaining  such 
economy?  Most  middle  managers  consider  themselves  victims  of  either 
tpp  little  or  too  much.  They  may  not  always  be  the  best  judges  of  the 
%<golden  mean,"  but  all  too  often  they  can  make  a  good  case  to  demonstrate 
that  they  are  "left  high  and  dry"  or  altogether  "snowed  under." 

Despite  some  technical  advances  such  as  the  introduction  of  teletype 
equipment,  communication  as  an  art  has  remained  amazingly  antiquated. 
All  one  can  say  is  that  we  are  doing  about  as  well  as  Roman  administrators 
did,  except  that  departmental  officers  and  provincial  governors  in  the  days 
of  the  Empire  were  not  bothered  with  the  obnoxious  effects  of  the  type- 
writer  and  modern  multicopying  devices.  For  ordinary  uses,  the  "memo" 
reigns  supreme,  and  usually  in  triplicate.  Few  have  stopped  to  ponder  the 
incredible  investment  of  time  that  goes  into  the  manufacture  and  the 
consumption  of  administrative  communications. 

^  High-grade  staff  people  processing  the  raw  materials  for  official  "issu- 
ances," lawyers  scanning  "rough  copies"  with  the  eagle  eye  characteristic  of 
their  craft,  draftsmen  adding  their  flourishes,  busy  line-executives  adorning 
the  margin  with  their  "queries,"  and  solemn  men  bickering  at  the  confer- 
ence table  over  commas  and  periods — all  of  this  is  part  of  the  tortuous 
gestation.  Then  the  ditto  machines  start  humming,  and  the  cloudburst 
comes  down.  "Did  you  read  the  latest  one  on  paper  salvage?"  "Heavens, 
no  I  My  girl  just  puts  it  into  the  file." 

A  wide  field  exists  to  the  imaginative  communication-engineer  to  devise 
ways  of  cutting  down  the  volume  of  waste  motion.  Use  of  short  forms  is 
one  approach,  but  it  is  more  fascinating  to  think  of  substituting  for  the 
rolling  paragraph  such  things  as  flash  signals  or  color  patterns  or  shorthand 
symbols  or  pictorial  strips.  Short  of  this,  there  is  the  possibility  of  aiding 
the  consumer  by  getting  down  closer  to  basic  English.16  Establishment 
of  agency-wide  issuance  control,  though  adding  a  new  unit,  has  paid  its 
way  because  of  both  its  braking  effect  and  the  great  convenience  of  locat- 
ing quickly  particular  kinds  of  communications  identified  by  series — direc- 
tives, orders,  instructions,  informational  bulletins. 

This  is  clear,  however.  The  mass  of  written  communications  now  tradi- 
tional in  large-scale  enterprise  eats  up  too  many  office  hours  at  the  receiving 
end  as  well  as  at  the  point  of  origin.  Moreover,  in  the  very  embarrassment 
of  riches,  most  systems  of  administrative  communication  fail  to  provide  an 

le  Mention  should  be  made  particularly  of  the  vigorous  campaign  for  increased  read- 
ability of  written  communications  carried  forward  by  the  Social  Security  Board.  See  also 
above  Ch.  17,  "Government  by  Procedure,"  sec.  4,  "Creation  and  Criteria." 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  411 

even  coverage  of  significant  information.  Priorities  are  ill-defined,  and  the 
trivialr-tends  to  drown  the  essential.  With  "all  the  stuff  that  comes  down," 
the  middle  manager  may  still  know  very  little  about  executive  thinking  at 
the  top.  And  though  he  tries  to  keep  abreast  of  developments,  he  may  fall 
into  the  defensive  habit  of  reading  only  when  he  "has  the  time  for  it."  Judg- 
ing by  what  evidence  we  have,17  top-level  issuances  ordinarily  enter  the 
mind  of  an  organization  only  slowly,  and  by  no  means  uniformly. 

Two-Way  Traffic  of  Thought.  Fortunately,  downward  communication 
to  enable  middle  management  to  operate  as  the  elongation  of  top-level  di- 
rection is  today  seldom  strictly  a  one-way  affair.  Effective  communication 
enunciates  thought,  and  institutional  thought  travels  increasingly  on  two- 
way  avenues.  Downward  communication  reaches  the  ear  of  the  middle  man- 
ager most  clearly  when  its  substance  relates  to  his  own  thinking— when  he 
finds  his  own  ideas  mirrored  in  it.  Expressed  in  terms  of  a  general  rule, 
we  may  say  that  communication  of  policy  gains  in  effectiveness  in  rough' 
proportion  to  the  scope  of  active  participation  of  middle  management  in 
the  policy-making  process. 

To  a  certain  extent,  of  course,  the  middle  manager  is  always  a  policy- 
maker. Not  only  does  he  take  part  in  policy  formulation  by  translating 
strategy  into  tactics,  by  tracing  out  top  determinations  into  line  activities, 
by  framing  operating  policies  under  his  own  responsibility.  He  is  also  a 
policy-maker  indirectly — by  implicit  or  explicit  reference,  in  his  reporting 
function,  to  existing  weaknesses  in  the  administrative  approach,  inadequacies 
in  current  policies,  and  emerging  problems  and  issues  that  warrant  top- 
level  consideration.18  However,  in  these  respects  his  role  in  policy  formula- 
tion is  intermittent  and  incidental.  For  best  results,  his  participation  in  the 
policy-making  process  should  be  continuous  and  take  form  in  an  organized 
manner. 

There  are  many  different  ways  for  achieving  continuous  participation 
in  an  organized  fashion,  and  most  of  them  admit  of  application  even  below 
the  intermediate  stratum  of  middle  management.19  More  important  than 
individual  devices  such  as  the  staff  meeting,20  is  the  habit  of  up-and-down 
and  across-the-board  consultation21  that  only  top  management  is  in  a  posi- 

17  For  some  valuable  insights  based  on  specific  inquiry  into  the  percentage-wise  distribu- 
tion of  knowledge  about  policy  pronouncements,  administrative  orders,  and  instructions,  see 
Corson,  John  J.,  "Weak  Links  in  the  Chain  of  Command,"  Public  Opinion  Quarterly,  1945, 
Vol.  9,  p.  346  if. 

18  For  a  discussion  of  the  dynamics  of  administrative  policy-making,  see  above  Ch.  16, 
"The  Formulation  of  Administrative  Policy,"  sec.  4,  "External  Influences   in  Administrative 
Policy.'* 

10  Sec  below  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec.  4,  "Supervision  and  Employee  Initia- 
tive"; Ch.  24,  "Personal  Standards,"  sec.  6,  "Employee  Relations." 

20  For  a  discussion  of  the  j^taff  meeting  as  a  device  of  organizing  administrative  analysis, 
see  below  Ch.  20,  "Administrative  Self-Improvement,"  sec.  2,  "Organization  for  Administrative 
Analysis." 

21  Cf.  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "Bureaucracy  and  Consultation,"  Review  of  Politics,  1939,  Vol. 

1,  p.  84  ff. 


412  THE  TASKS  OF   MIDDLE   MANAGEMENT 

tion  to  instill  in  all  parts  of  the  organization.  A  feeble  or  small-minded 
top  management,  offended  by  any  "criticism"  from  within,  is  obviously 
unable  to  foster  such  habits  of  consultation,  however  much  lip  service  it 
may  pay  the  abstract  principle  of  common  thought.  Helpful  suggestions 
and  new  ideas  will  not  come  forth  when  they  fail  to  find  eager  takers.  Yet, 
though  the  habit  of  sharing  policy-thinking  should  be  accorded  first 
place,  particular  arrangements  commend  themselves  for  their  habit-forming 
effects. 

In  the  operation  of  a  departmental  bureau,  for  instance,  it  will  be  profit- 
able— as  experience  has  demonstrated"2 — for  the  bureau  chief  to  meet  every 
day  for  a  brief  conference  with  his  assistant  chiefs;  assemble  once  a  week  a 
somewhat  wider  circle  of  key  officers;  spend  at  least  an  hour  twice  a  month 
with  all  his  division,  branch,  and  unit  chiefs  and  their  right-hand  men  in 
order  to  focus  attention  on  matters  of  common  significance;  and  get  to- 
gether once  a  year  with  all  his  field-office  managers,  and  more  often  with 
smaller  groups  of  them,  perhaps  region  by  region,  and  with  the  regional 
directors  as  well.23  This  would  not  dispose  of  the  customary  media  of  cir- 
culating information — bureau  bulletins,  periodic  program  and  activity  sur- 
veys, weekly  field  letters.  Needless  to  say,  observing  the  proprieties  of  a 
conference  schedule  is  one  thing,  but  knowing  how  to  make  a  go  of  it  is 
still  something  different.  A  sour-looking  chairman  who  brightens  up  only 
when  he  can  tightly  hold  on  to  his  own  monologue  would  wreck  any 
kind  of  staff  meeting  in  no  time. 

It  is  probably  true  that  the  total  intellectual  resources  available  within 
the  structure  of  large-scale  enterprise  are  today  still  far  from  being  fully 
utilized.  The  effect  is  exactly  like  making  a  high-priced  engineer  count 
building  permits.  He  gets  disgusted  and  indifferent  to  the  interests  of  his 
employer;  and  the  employer  wastes  four-fifths  of  the  engineer's  salary  be- 
cause counting  building  permits,  if  it  has  to  be  done  at  all,  could  be  done 
by  the  lowest-paid  employee.  Strangely,  the  loss  in  both  efficiency  and 
economy  that  results  from  leaving  untapped  much  of  the  latent  ability  in 
an  organization  is  frequently  caused  deliberately.  Too  many  top  executives 
have  remained  enslaved  to  the  obsolete  notion  that  wide  internal  participa- 
tion in  policy  thinking  undermines  their  "authority."  It  is  time  for  them 
to  see  that  they  are  wrong. 

If  evidence  from  money-making  private  business  be  preferred,  they 
would  find  it  in  the  record  of  "multiple  .management" — a  catch-phrase 
made  famous  by  Baltimore's  business-minded  Charles  P.  McCormick.24  In 
his  company — largest  wholesale  spice  dealers  in  the  United  States — McCor- 
mick  provided  for  three  elective  employee  bodies:  a  junior  board  of  direc- 

22  Cf.  Corson,  John  J.,  "The  Role  of  Communication  in  the  Process  of  Administration," 
Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  7  ff. 

23  Cf.  also  above  Ch.   12,  "Field  Organization,"  sec.  3,  "Field-Headquarters  Relations.'* 

24  See  his  Multiple  Management,  New  York:  Harper,  1938. 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE   MANAGEMENT  413 

tors,  a  factory  board,  and  a  sales  and  advertising  board.  The  prime  function 
of  these  three  organs  is  to  feed  ideas  into  the  senior  board  of  stockholders. 
Multiple  management  has  done  so  well  that  some  500  firms  have  followed 
suit,  including  Eric  Johnston's  three  Spokane  companies.  Its  success  is  tes- 
timony to  a  generally  sound  conception. 

Taking  Orders.  Middle  management  is  in  the  "chain  of  command" — in 
fact  it  represents  most  of  the  length  of  this  chain.  Looking  downward,  the 
middle  manager  exercises  his  formal  authority  in  large  measure  by  giving  or- 
ders. Simultaneously,  however,  he  is  subject  to  the  formal  authority  of  his 
superiors.  If  the  familiar  adage  about  learning  to  obey  in  order  to  learn 
to  command  settled  everything,  the  middle  manager,  usually  serving  his 
way  up,  would  be  an  ideal  commander.  And  the  ideal  commander  would 
also  excel  at  taking  orders. 

Taking  orders  is  in  many  ways  merely  the  reverse  of  self-identification 
with  institutional  purposes  and  objectives.  When  such  self-identification  is 
complete  or  nearly  complete,  the  order  from  higher  authority  is  essentially 
an  affirmative  gesture,  a  signal  to  go  ahead,  more  of  a  timing  device  than 
an  indication  of  aims  or  direction.  No  one  would  see  a  problem  in  taking 
an  order  when  the  order  for  all  practical  purposes  is  his  own,  or — because 
of  prior  consultation — at  least  in  part  his  own. 

It  is  a  rather  different  proposition,  and  one  causing  varying  degrees  of 
strain,  to  execute  orders  that  cannot  readily  be  accommodated  even  within 
a  reasonably  flexible  frame  of  institutional  allegiance.  When  top  manage- 
ment is  overbearing  and  yet  has  little  standing  with  the  organization;  or 
has  embarked  upon  a  new  and  dubious  course  without  attempting  to  take 
the  middle  managers  into  its  confidence;  or  appears  to  subordinate  acknowl- 
edged long-range  objectives  to  opportunistic  maneuvering — in  such  circum- 
stances compliance  with  orders  may  hurt. 

This  kind  of  emotional  conflict  illuminates  again  the  narrow  foundation 
on  which  formal  authority  rests.25  No  order  executes  itself.  It  moves  down 
the  chain  of  command  only  so  far  as  its  motion  is  sustained  by  the  impetus 
furnished  on  each  level  of  subleadership.  To  be  sure,  compliance  is  bol- 
stered up  by  discipline  and  by  machinery  for  the  enforcement  of  discipline.26 
But  disciplinary  machinery  is  a  far  cry  from  joyful  zest  of  individual  self- 
exertion. 

In  the  face  of  disciplinary  threats,  all  one  needs  to  do  is  turn  on  a  show 
of  compliance.  "Getting  by"  is  enough  not  to  "get  caught."  Or  one  may  "lie 
low,"  inching  ahead  reluctantly  only  when  prodded.  Or  one  may  flatly 
refuse  to  budge,  though  always  duly  covered.  Bureaucratic  sabotage  is  by 
no  means  confined  to  public  administration;  it  occurs  to  the  same  extent  in 
private  management.  Orders  can  be  "misunderstood."  Excuses  can  be 

25  Sec  above  Ch.  13,  "Informal  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Elements  of  Informal  Organiza- 
tion." 

26  Sec  below  Ch.  21,  "Morale  and  Discipline." 


414  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE   MANAGEMENT 

found  to  explain  sluggishness.  "Buck-passing"  can  be  practiced  with  con- 
siderable refinement.  Conceding  that  there  are  practical  limits  to  passive 
resistance,  we  arc  once  more  reminded  of  the  all-pervading  influence  of 
restraints  that  only  a  living  service-ideology  can  impose.  Once  more  we 
recognize  that  faithful  execution  of  orders  in  the  last  analysis  springs  from 
common  agreement  on  institutional  ends. 

At  the  same  time,  ability  to  take  orders  does  not  imply  blind  subservience. 
The  middle  manager  for  whom  "orders  are  orders"  always,  may  get  his 
organization  into  serious  trouble  when  he  fails  to  speak  up  on  obstacles  which 
only  he  can  spot  from  the  vantage  point  of  his  line  experience.  He  simply 
does  not  do  his  job  if  he  dispenses  with  his  personal  judgment.  Orders 
may  indeed  be  susceptible  of  misunderstanding.  They  may  overshoot  the 
mark.  They  may  be  overtaken  by  rapidly  changing  conditions.  Then  it  is 
plainly  in  the  interest  of  the  whole  organization  immediately  to  check  back 
with  the  supreme  command. 

On  the  other  hand,  everything  would  soon  stall  if  middle  management 
made  it  a  general  practice  to  attempt  a  virtual  verification  of  each  order 
by  appealing  to  the  next  higher  level  for  elaboration.  Here,  too,  and  in 
the  interpretation  of  orders  for  the  lower  levels,  alert  judgment  is  prerequi- 
site. It  will  err  rarely  when  the  broad  picture  of  administrative  strategy 
and  the  "way  we  operate"  are  clearly  understood  by  all  concerned.27 

Tribulations  of  the  Operator.  In  the  conduct  of  line  business,  the  mid- 
dle manager  carries  a  responsibility  that  is  well-nigh  all-inclusive.  He  has 
to  "get  the  work  out,"  and  all  of  it — and  fast.  Yet,  especially  in  the  realm 
of  public  administration,  his  hands  are  tied  in  many  ways,  though  in  each 
instance  in  the  name  of  good  management. 

He  does  not  freely  pick  his  subordinates;  they  are  handed  him  through 
certification  from  an  eligibility  register  by  the  central  personnel  agency,  and 
his  actual  choice  is  generally  limited  by  the  "rule  of  three."  He  is  not 
allowed  to  grade  them  up  or  down;  that  is  a  matter  of  a  ceremonious jig-_ 
marolfr  known  as  ^classification,  and  in  this  rigmarole  his  own  judgment 
may  be  the  least  important  factor.  He  is,  of  course,  unable  simply  to  tell 
them  never  again  to  come  before  his  eyes;  he  must  state  a  "cause"  in  writ- 
ing, and  the  matter  may  not  rest  at  that,  for  it  is  not  unusual  among  govern- 
mental jurisdictions  to  allow  a  dismissed  employee  to  carry  his  case  before 
the  civil  service  commission.28  These  restrictions  are  not  devoid  of  reasons 
that  no  one  would  want  to  brush  aside  lightly.29  They  are  nonetheless  very 
real  impairments  of  the  middle  manager's  freedom  of  operational  option. 

If  we  turn  to  government-wide  regulations  on  budgeting,  auditing,  ao 

27  Ability  to  take  orders  has  been  treated  as  the  first  requirement  of  effective  middle 
management  by  Frederick  J.  George,  "How  To  Be  a  Good  Junior  Executive,"  Canadian  Bun- 
ness,  1941,  Vol.  14,  p.  88  ff. 

28  This  is  not  generally  true  of  the  federal  government. 

29  For  a  fuller  discussion  of  public  personnel  administration  in  the  context  of  adminis- 
trative responsibility,  fee  below  Ch.  24,  "Personnel  Standards.*' 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  413 

counting,  procurement,  and  a  host  of  housekeeping  functions,  the  topog* 
raphy  of  management  grows  increasingly  befuddling.  Like  poison  ivy 
climbing  all  over  the  thicket,  the  prohibitions  seem  to  outdo  the  incentives. 
In  the  end,  the  middle  manager's  perspective  may  become  badly  distorted. 
He  may  feel  that  a  serious  backlog  in  substantive  business  may  not  be  as 
troublesome  as  an  infraction  of  general  housekeeping  procedures.  If  he 
falls  behind  in  his  operations,  he  may  find  charitable  judges  among  his 
superiors;  if  he  gets  "fouled  up"  on  government- wide  prescriptions  about 
the  handling  of  vouchers,  for  instance,  a  central  agency  may  start  snarling 
at  his  department. 

A  pretty  persuasive  case  can  be  made  for  the  contention  that  American 
public  administration  has  become  top-heavy  with  central  controls.  Certainly 
this  is  a  question  to  which  careful  research  might  be  devoted  with  great 
benefit.  Meanwhile,  the  line  operator  has  to  "sweat  it  out."  We  need 
little  imagination  to  visualize  the  many  instances  in  which  he  feels  arrested 
in  the  application  of  straight  commonsense  by  hard  and  fast  rules  that  to 
lim  have  no  rhyme  or  reason  whatsoever. 

Thinking  in  Larger  Terms.  Self -identification  with  institutional  pur- 
Doses,  as  we  observed  earlier,  is  a  condition  vital  to  productive  middle  man- 
igement.  But,  as  with  all  good  things,  there  can  be  too  much  of  it.  Ex- 
:esses  may  present  themselves  on  different  scales.  The  most  common  type 
}f  excess  arises  from  the  imnicdiacy  of  the  operator's  concern  with  the  par- 
:icular  province  of  his  responsibility.  His  bureau,  division,  section,  or  unit, 
Deing  the  foundation  of  his  status  within  the  organization,  insidiously  ex- 
Dands  its  claim  on  his  mind.  Eventually  he  comes  to  look  upon  himself  as 
he  living  personification  of  this  one  link  in  the  chain  of  the  cooperative 
process.  He  "lives  for  his  work"  to  the  exclusion  of  outside  considerations, 
>ven  though  he  knows  that  theoretically  its  worth  could  not  be  assessed 
without  regard  for  the  organization  as  a  whole. 

This  attitude  accounts  for  the  peculiar  tendency  on  the  part  of  the  aver- 
age line  official  toward  functional  self-aggrandizement,  however  innocent 
and  unconscious.  He  seeks  expansion — bigger  and  better  programs,  bigger 
and  better  appropriations,  bigger  and  better  staffs — not  just  for  the  exhilara- 
tion of  sheer  magnitude,  but  because  to  him  his  segment  of  the  total  effort 
is  the  most  important  one,  the  hub  of  the  entire  enterprise.  Top  manage- 
ment, the  budget  officer,  and  the  personnel  director  are  all  "off  the  beam" 
when  they  fail  to  see  it  that  way.  Or  perhaps  they  are  even  jealous  and  want 
to  hold  him  down.  So  he  thinks  he  has  to  play  his  cards  astutely  and  never 
put  them  on  the  table  face  up. 

In  contrast  with  the  tug-of-war  between  the  particular  and  the  general 
within  the  agency,  excessive  self-identification  with  institutional  purposes 
also  occurs  on  a  department-wide  scale.  When  it  is  instinctively  assumed, 
for  example,  that  the  department  is  always  right,  its  officialdom  may  be  dis- 
tinguished by  high  morale  and  great  elan,  but  to  the  same  extent  the  depart- 


416  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

ment  is  severely  handicapped  for  open-minded  interdepartmental  coopera- 
tion. In  the  modern  service  state,30  governmental  functions  intermesh  and 
intermingle.  Few  departments  have  clearly  defined  monopolies  on  particular 
areas  of  public  service.  Far  more  frequently  several  departments  touch 
one  and  the  same  area  from  different  angles.  When  one  agency  advances 
in  a  given  area,  other  agencies  are  inevitably  affected.  In  consequence,  as 
there  is  intradepartmental  competition  between  bureaus  and  divisions, 
so  we  encounter  rivalry  between  agencies  themselves.  Nor  is  this  all.  De- 
partment heads  may  also  display  a  keen  competitive  sense  in  relation  to 
the  chief  executive. 

On  the  levels  of  middle  management,  the  innate  particularism  can  be 
mitigated  only  by  a  systematically  cultivated  inclination  to  think  in  larger 
terms.  Top  leadership  may  do  much  to  widen  the  horizon  of  the  line 
official.  But  appropriate  indoctrination  should  be  government-wide.  This  is 
not  impossible  of  attainment.  We  could  place  much  more  stress  on  middle 
management  as  a  unified  profession,  and  develop  arrangements  to  move 
middle  managers  about  within  their  department  and  interdepartmentally 
to  check  the  danger  of  introversion.  We  could  thus  provide  a  climate  favor- 
able to  the  growth  of  an  administrative  doctrine  that  would  assure  primacy 
to  the  more  comprehensive  public  interest— in  conformity  with  political 
responsibility.  Such  a  doctrine  is  the  logical  center-piece  of  a  democratically 
conceived  service  ideology, 

3.  RUNNING  THE  SHOW 

Problems  of  Delegation.  Top  management  expects  of  the  line  official 
that  in  due  time  he  will  be  able  to  report,  "Mission  accomplished."  In 
carrying  out  his  mission,  he  must  think  and  plan  for  himself.  No  detailed 
instruction  coming  from  above  can  ever  take  the  place  of  his  own  experi- 
ence and  foresight.  In  fact,  he  is  the  chosen  instrument  to  settle  the  details, 
thus  freeing  the  leadership  of  his  agency  for  policy  consideration.  To  do  his 
job  he  needs  a  considerable  degree  of  leeway  of  action.  No  one  would 
quarrel  with  the  axiom  that  the  authority  delegated  to  him  should  meas- 
ure up  to  the  breadth  of  his  responsibility  for  results.  However,  it  is  a  dif- 
ferent matter  to  transform  the  axiom  into  reality. 

Generally  speaking,  delegation  of  authority  has  been  hesitant  and  grudg- 
ing. This  can  be  explained  in  part  by  the  rather  disorganized  and  sometimes 
erratic  manner  in  which  American  legislatures  have  exacted  accountability 
from  politically  responsible  administrators.  When  agency  heads  can  be 
singed  so  badly  because  of  relatively  minor  slips  of  distant  subordinates, 
the  general  inclination  will  be  to  hold  the  reins  of  top  control  more  tightly 
than  i$  ideal  for  good  management.  Part  of  the  explanation  lies  also  in  the 
traditions  of  the  "spoils  system"  of  an  earlier  day  when  line  officials  could 

80  Cf.  above  Ch.  5,  "The  Social  Function  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  2,  "The  Needs 
of  the  Service  State." 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  417 

not  be  trusted  to  stand  on  their  own  feet  administratively.  Still  another 
part  of  the  explanation  must  be  sought  in  the  same  tendencies  that  have 
retarded  adequate  decentralization  of  activities  to  the  field.31  For  greatest 
efficiency,  delegation  of  authority  to  middle  management  could  by  and  large 
go  much  further  than  it  has  so  far. 

Even  where  delegation  of  authority  is  reasonably  adequate,  we  often 
find  unnecessarily  extensive  requirements  for  higher  approval  of  whole 
categories  of  more  important  decisions.  These  requirements  throw  great 
burdens  on  the  administrative  process  and  are  hardly  conducive  to  the 
formation  of  a  strong  sense  of  responsibility.  It  is  sounder  to  devise  report- 
ing relationships  through  which  danger  signs  become  automatically  visible,32 
both  to  top  management  and  to  the  operating  officials  themselves.  Appraisal 
of  the  outcome  of  administrative  action  in  success  or  failure  is  superior  to 
cumbersome  mechanics  of  higher  review  of  proposed  action. 

Reinforcing  the  Line  Sector.  It  is  the  hallmark  of  effective  middle 
management  to  be  able  to  stand  on  its  own  feet,  at  the  same  time  knowing 
where  to  get  help  when  help  is  needed.  Much  help  will  be  secured  by  the 
simple  method  of  checking  with  the  "crowd  across  the  hall"  or  by  pooling 
resources  with  adjacent  line  sectors.  Indeed,  large-scale  enterprise  cannot 
achieve  unity  of  purpose  without  a  constant  process  of  cross-referencing — 
drawing  into  both  planning  and  operations  all  the  thought,  information, 
and  experience  available  within  the  total  organization;  enriching  each  activ- 
ity by  tying  it  into  the  whole  program;  and  amplifying  the  stream  of  insti- 
tutional intelligence  so  that  line  officials  and  staff  officers  can  maintain 
elbow  touch  with  each  other  and  among  themselves.  As  a  student  of  middle 
management  has  said,  "The  organization  of  crosswise  relationships  is  one 
of  the  foremost  problems  of  today  and  tomorrow."33 

The  wide-awake  operator  knows  many  turns  for  bringing  these  cross- 
wise relationships  into  play—down  to  sources  of  "grapevine"  and  the  un- 
hurried conversation  in  the  executive  dining  room.  Line  officials  see  eye  to 
eye  on  many  things  and  usually  share  their  worries  without  reserve.  They 
feel  rather  differently  toward  staff  people,  especially  from  the  top  offices. 
Yet  prudent  use  of  staff  facilities  pays  the  middle  manager  high  dividends, 
and  he  knows  it.  Growth  of  at  least  rudimentary  staff  organs  within  the 
line  organization  itself  has  made  him  more  enthusiastic  about  assistance 
from  staff  personnel  than  he  used  to  be.  Higher-level  staffs,  though  indis- 
pensable to  him  on  major  problems,34  are  still  somewhat  suspect  for  their 
uncanny  ways  of  ferreting  out  hidden  issues  that  call  for  much  explaining 
on  his  part— and  occasionally  make  him  look  very  sheepish. 

31  Sec  above  Ch.  12,  "Field  Organization,"  sec.  2,  "Centralization  and  Decentralization/' 

32  Cf.  Pfirtncr,  John  M.,  "How  To  Delegate  Authority,"  Public  Management,  1943,  Vol. 
25,  p.  351tf. 

33  Niles,  Mary  C.  H.,  Middle  Management,  p.  52,  New  York:  Harper,  1941. 

34  See  below  Ch.  20,  "Administrative  Self -Improvement." 


418  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

In  the  light  of  the  historic  development  of  staff  facilities,  it  cannot  cause 
astonishment  that  as  a  rule  the  staff  organs  lodged  down  in  the  line  are 
the  weakest.  Departmental  top-office  staffs  rank  higher  in  competence,  and 
central  staff  establishments  may  rate  one  or  two  notches  above  these.  Not- 
withstanding the  greater  purchasing  power  of  the  higher  levels,  staff  talent 
ought  to  be  more  evenly  distributed.  This  would  also  allay  the  fears  of 
middle  managers  that  staff  personnel  called  on  for  help  might  in  effect  lay 
down  the  law  for  the  operators  to  live  with,  and  then  nimbly  depart  from 
the  scene.35 

Organizing  for  Worl^.  Line  officials,  like  every  one  else,  may  pride  them- 
selves on  organizing  their  "shop"  without  ever  stopping  to  think  about 
organizing  their  own  job.36  One  ailment  widespread  among  operators  is  a 
pernicious  preoccupation  with  lesser  details — "the  petty  done,  the  undone 
vast."  In  administration,  detail  is  seldom  trivial;  but  it  is  also  true  that  the 
competent  middle  manager  must  possess  a  sure  feeling  for  the  significant 
detail  which  alone  justifies  his  personal  attention.  A  kindred  ailment  is  the 
abandon  with  which  some  line  officials  throw  themselves  into  the  routine 
technicalities  of  operating  processes.  They  keep  themselves  so  busy  that 
no  minute  is  left  for  the  contemplative  pause.  In  the  end  they  have  run  so 
dry  that  the  thought  of  thinking  drives  them  frantic;  so  they  have  to  go 
on  being  busy. 

It  is  generally  simply  an  indication  of  a  bad  job  of  self-organization  to 
be  always  pressed  for  time.  This  is  especially  serious  in  middle  manage- 
ment because  operators  stand  or  fall  with  their  capacity  for  dealing  with 
larger  groups  of  human  beings  who  look  to  them  for  guidance  and  stimula- 
tion. Time  is  of  the  essence  in  all  human  relationships — time  for  confer- 
ences, time  for  complaints,  time  for  advice,  time  for  instruction,  time  for  a 
joke  or  a  few  friendly  words  wherever  the  opportunity  presents  itself. 

A  line  official  must  therefore  be  able  not  merely  to  project  his  influence 
upon  the  entire  range  of  operations  in  his  charge  but  also  to  detach  himself 
mentally  from  the  day-by-day  activities,  at  least  at  sufficiently  frequent  inter- 
vals. Only  with  such  detachment  can  he  be  a  reliable  overseer  of  the  "whole 
show."  Only  by  figuratively  stepping  back  during  his  quieter  hours  can 
he  preserve  his  perspective. 

Even  if  he  holds  that  thinking  is  none  of  his  business,  the  pressures  on 
him  will  compel  him  to  pick  one  or  two  understudies  and  to  build  up  his 
key  men.  He  will  have  to  learn  how  to  anticipate  program  changes  and 
emerging  problems.  He  will  have  to  fit  his  own  way  of  operating  into  the 
working  methods  of  his  immediate  superior  and  the  mode  of  business 

35  Theoretically,  of  course,  staff  personnel  arc  outside  the  chain  of  command.  As  a 
statement  on  organization  and  methods  work  issued  January  8,  1945,  by  the  British  Treasury 
formulates  it,  departmental  organization  and  methods  branches  "will  operate  by  advice  ten- 
dered and  not  by  instructions  issued."  Of  course,  such  advice  may  in  concrete  circum- 
stances be  equal  to  command. 

86  Cf.  Niles,  op.  tit.  above  in  note  33,  ch.  11. 


THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT  419 

prevalent  in  those  units  which  with  his  unit  form  a  tactical  entity.  If  he  is 
far  enough  down  in  the  chain  of  command,  he  must  not  only  be  readily 
accessible  to  all  of  his  first-line  supervisors  but  he  must  also  look  over  their 
shoulders  to  find  out  how  they  are  doing. 

Whatever  his  location  in  the  hierarchy,  he  must  be  alert  to  opportunities 
for  developing  talent  among  his  subordinates  and  be  sufficiently  unselfish 
to  let  promising  men  and  women  go  on  to  higher  responsibilities  outside 
his  "shop."  One  of  the  greatest  qualities  of  middle  management  lies  in 
training  employees  for  advancement  all  over  the  organization.  This  puts 
a  premium  on  the  point  of  view  of  the  "generalise—looking  at  the  whole 
picture  rather  than  at  any  particular  specialization. 

Reporting  Schemes.  In  the  two-way  traffic  of  thought,  the  upward  flow 
of  reports  and  recommendations  is  at  least  as  significant  to  the  character 
of  institutional  intelligence  as  downward  communication.  Line  reporting 
brings  top  management  "down  to  earth."  No  fine-spun  plan  is  worth  a 
tinker's  dam  unless  it  holds  up  in  the  stress  of  operations.  Without  realistic 
line  reporting,  top-level  direction  would  grope  in  darkness.  Equally  im- 
portant is  the  contribution  of  operating  reports  to  the  maintenance  of 
internal  control. 

All  programming  and  scheduling  must  be  buttressed  by  reporting  re- 
quirements. But  reporting  can  run  wild.  In  not  a  few  administrative  or- 
ganizations everybody  seems  to  need  to  know  everything,  and  in  the  ensuing 
flood  of  information  everybody  is  drowned  alike.  In  the  system  of  informa- 
tional channels  the  locks  perform  a  function  no  less  urgent  than  the  channels 
themselves. 

In  the  first  place,  in  order  to  be  of  use  for  purposes  of  executive  control, 
raw  information  must  continually  be  translated  into  control  information— 
by  digesting,  abstracting,  and  underscoring  of  relevant  points.  Secondly., 
informational  priorities  must  be  clearly  expressed  in  designing  the  report- 
ing system.  Thirdly,  time  and  again  the  question  must  be  raised  whether 
each  periodic  report  actually  meets  concrete,  needs. 

By  raising  this  question  with  commendable  stubbornness,  the  Army 
Service  Forces  during  World  War  II,  for  instance,  manufactured  uncounted 
workdays  of  time  saved  by  getting  rid  of  reports  of  no  or  marginal  utility. 
Reporting  requirements,  once  established,  have  great  survival  power,  not- 
withstanding the  disappearance  of  original  demand.  Moreover,  information 
serially  supplied  by  operators  may  to  them  be  "just  red  tape"  because  no 
one  has  told  them  exactly  why  top  management  must  have  the  information 
and  how  it  might  be  made  to  render  service  to  them,  too,  in  appraising  line 
activities.  Finally,  in  many  instances  the  data  dredged  up  in  reports  may 
only  tell  half  of  the  story,  which  is  sometimes  worse  than  saying  nothing 
at  all.  To  illustrate,  trying  to  judge  workload  by  measuring  the  quantity  of 
licenses  issued  or  inspections  carried  out  would  be  foolish  if  routine  cases 


420  THE  TASKS  OF  MIDDLE  MANAGEMENT 

were  not  segregated  from  more  complex  ones,  or  if  the  variables  of  com- 
plexity were  not  objectively  identified. 

Keeping  Records.  Administration  can  mean  many  things,  but  it  is 
always  a  lot  of  paperwork.  Federal  records  now  in  existence  are  estimated 
to  amount  to  some  16,000,000  or  18,000,000  cubic  feet,  with  an  annual  accu- 
mulation of  no  less  than  1,000,000.37  Most  of  this  is  made  up  of  operating 
records.  However,  resort  to  documentation  of  past  undertakings  and  full- 
fledged  record  reference — like  institutional  library  reference — is  becoming 
growingly  essential  to  policy  determination  and  top-staff  activity.38  Record 
management  as  a  specialized  service  has  made  marked  strides  recently.  It 
may  prove  to  be  a  highly  beneficial  influence  in  strengthening  the  memory 
of  an  organization;  evoke  a  clearer  sense  of  consistency  in  its  collective 
mind;  and  keep  its  officials  from  improvising  anew  for  each  day  or  conduct- 
ing the  concert  "by  ear." 

Bodies  of  records  may  look  like  so  much  besmudged  and  dust-covered 
paper.  Actually  they  are  "repositories  of  information,"39  and  should  be 
treated  as  such.  "The  objectives  of  the  record  function  are:  (1)  the  receipt, 
custody,  and  care  of  the  record  material  belonging  to  an  organization; 
(2)  its  maintenance  in  such  condition  that  the  material  and  the  informa- 
tion contained  therein  may  be  readily  available;  and  (3)  its  proper  final 
disposition."40  In  the  disposition,  archival  interests  must  be  safeguarded. 
This  explains  the  role  the  National  Archives  is  playing  in  superintending 
the  final  disposition  of  federal  records.41 

Documentation  of  transactions  is  an  aid  not  only  in  achieving  responsi- 
bility—the record  tells— but  also  in  making  "know  how"  less  fugitive  and 
more  of  an  institutional  property.  When  the  working  files  on  each  level 
of  middle  management  are  reasonably  complete  and  in  good  order,  it  is 
much  easier  to  pull  operators  out  of  their  "shop"  for  more  important  assign- 
ments because  the  successor  can  find  his  way  without  asking  innumerable . 
questions  or  figuring  out  each  thing  again.  Orderliness  of  control  is  in 
large  part  dependent  on  orderliness  of  documentation.  No  middle  man- 
ager is  truly  up  to  his  job  if  he  fails  to  assure  himself  of  good  record 
administration. 


37  Wilson,   William   J.,   "Analysis  of  Government  Records:   An   Emerging  Profession,'* 
Library  Quarterly,  1946,  Vol.  16.  p.  1.    This  paper  opens  up  many  of  the  aspects  of  modern 
record  administration. 

38  See  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz  and  Others,  "A  Reference  Service  for  the  Administrator," 
Interagency  Records  Administration  Conference:  Washington,  April  27,  1945  (mimeographed). 

8ftChatfield,  Helen   L.,   "The  Role  of  the  Archivist  in  Public  Administration/'  p.  5, 
National  Archives:  Washington,  May,  1942  (mimeographed). 

40  Chatfield,  Helen  L.,  'The  Problem  of  Records  from  the  Standpoint  of  Management," 
American  Archivist,  1940,  Vol.  3,  p.  97. 

41  The   National   Archives   has  issued   much   useful   material  on   record  administration, 
especially  in  its  series  of  circulars, 


CHAPTER 


The  Art  of  Supervision 

1.  WHAT  Is  SUPERVISION? 

Direction  with  Authority.  Supervision  has  been  defined  as  the  direction, 
accompanied  by  authority,  of  the  work  of  others.  It  is  this  top-to-bottom 
chain  of  supervision  which  gives  coherence  to  any  organization. 

Supervision  in  its  purest  form  occurs  at  the  first  or  lowest  level  of  organi- 
zation— that  is,  the  direction-with-authority  over  workers  who  in  turn  direct 
no  one  else.  In  government  parlance,  this  lowest  level  is  referred  to  as  that 
of  the  first-line  supervisor.  In  industry  it  is  that  of  the  lead-man,  or  fore- 
man. In  an  army  it  is  that  of  the  corporal,  or  perhaps  the  sergeant/ It  is 
with  the  first-line  supervisor  that  most  of  our  discussion  here  will  deal. 

It  should  be  borne  in  mind,  however,  that  supervision  occurs  wherever 
there  are  groups  of  workers,  high  or  low  in  the  organization,  in  or  outside 
the  "chain  of  command."  In  true  staff  units,  for  instance,  one  employee  may 
oversee  another,  although  neither  has  any  power  of  direction  outside  his 
office.  Likewise  in  a  group  of  specialists,  the  head  specialist  may  supervise 
the  work  of  the  others,  although  his  authority  does  not  extend  into  th< 
organization;  it  is  not  related  to  other  workers  outside  .he  specialist  group. 
This  argument,  of  course,  spins  the  thread  of  command  pretty  fine  if  car- 
ried too  far.  Consider  that  the  staff  employee  or  specialist  may  wield  real 
influence  on  the  workers  in  other  units  even  if  he  does  it  informally  and 
outside  the  hierarchy,  by  the  force  of  his  personality,  by  the  excellence  of  his 
suggestions,  or  by  some  other  nonauthoritative  means. 

Concept  of  Functional  Foreman.  Frederick  W.  Taylor,  the  original  ex- 
ponent of  scientific  management,  recognized  this  factor  in  his  case  for  the 
"functional  foreman."  He  felt  that  the  highest  production  could  be  achieved 
if  each  special  aspect  of  the  worker's  task  was  commanded  by  a  foreman 
who  was  a  specialist  in  it.1  This  concept  of  multiple  direction— Taylor  broke 
it  into  eight  parts — is  no  longer  accepted,  at  least  in  theory.  Instead,  the 

1  Taylor's  most  important  work  was  published  in  1911  under  the  title  The  Principles  of 
Scientific  Management^  republished  New  York:  Harper,  1934. 

421 


422  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

modern  management  conception  calls  for  unity  of  command.  Each  worker 
is  to  have  only  one  boss.  The  specialist  has  no  direct  authority.  He  cannot 
give  orders  to  the  worker.  He  may  only  use  indirect  influence,  set  techni- 
cal standards,  and  so  on.  In  fact,  usually  his  influence  is  indirectly  exerted 
through  the  immediate  supervisor.  The  supervisor,  then,  is  the  boss  who 
has  immediate  and  personal  direction — with  authority — of  other  workers. 

Phases  of  Supervision.  Defined  in  terms  of  production,  the  supervisor 
is  responsible  for  getting  out  the  work  of  his  unit — for  its  quantity  and 
quality,  its  timing.VAnd  herein  lies  the  rub.  All  too  often  in  the  past,  man- 
agers and  supervisors  have  had  an  eye  on  production  rather  than  on  the 
basic  producers.  One  symptom  of  this  disease  has  been  the  practice  of  ap- 
pointing as  foreman  or  supervisor  the  best  worker  in  the  shop  or  office. 
The  typist  who  wrote  the  most  letters  per  hour  was  made  head  of  the 
stenographic  pool  because  she  was  the  best  worker.  As  if  by  her  very  ex- 
ample she  would  spur  the  others  on!  Usually  such  appointments  have 
brought  poor  results  because  of  failure  to  see  the  personal  side  of  the  job 
of  the  supervisor. 

A  similar  although  rarer  practice  especially  in  "red  tape"  organizations 
such  as  large  insurance  companies  and  government  offices  has  been  to  pro- 
mote the  "old  hand"  to  be  supervisor  because  he  "knows  the  ropes."  The 
ropes,  of  course,  vary  from  the  literal  version  aboard  a  sailing  vessel  to  the 
more  complicated  strands  of  laws  and  rules  in  a  federal  agency,  for  example. 
The  chap  who  has  been  around  long  enough  to  know  office  policy  and  pro- 
cedures, whom  one  sees  for  this  and  for  that — be  it  Form  57  or  309 — has 
great  value.  Again,  however,  supervisory  appointments  made  from  among 
such  people  ignore  the  key  to  the  supervisor's  job,  namely,  ability  to  work 
with  others  and  make  them  work  better,  i/ 

So  we  touch  early  on  the  three  phases  of  the  supervisor's  job:  (1)  sub- 
ptantive  or  technical — the  work  to  be  done;  (2)  institutional  or  adjective — 
policies  and  procedures  according  to  which  the  work  must  be  done; 
id  (3)  personal— the  handling  of  the  workers,  though  "handling"  is  not 
hie  best  word  for  it.  It  is  the  last  phase  which  will  concern  us  most.  Neither 
lie  work  nor  the  rules  are  the  key  to  supervision.  The  supervisor  must 
fcnow  both,  but  the  critical  knowledge  and  the  indispensable  skill  is  nothing 
Ijess  than  personal  leadership.2 

Scope  of  Supervision.  Since  our  emphasis  quite  naturally  is  on  the 
human  side  of  the  supervisor's  responsibilities,  we  may  very  quickly  glide 
'over  his  technical  and  institutional  responsibilities.  The  actual  content  of 
his  technical  responsibilities  will  vary  greatly  depending  on  the  product, 

2  There  is  a  considerable  body  of  literature  on  supervision.  A  helpful  guide  is  furnished 
by  Cooper,  Alfred  M.,  How  To  Supervise  People,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1941.  Super- 
vision is  also  treated  in  most  of  the  general  works  on  industrial  management,  such  as  Alford, 
L.  P.,  Principles  of  Industrial  Management,  New  York:  Ronald  Press,  1940.  On  general 
aspects  of  supervision  in  government,  see  especially  Cooper,  Alfred  M.,  Supervision  of  Govern- 
mental Employees,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1943. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  423 

work  process,  and  work  situation^  In  mass-production  industry,  the  lead- 
man  may  have  almost  no  direct  technical  responsibility,  except  for  quan- 
tity of  output.  Method  is  determined  higher  up.  Equipment  is  provided, 
and  materials  likewise.  Quality  control  is  also  out  of  his  hands  since  it  is 
the  immediate  concern  of  an  inspector. 

In  less  systematized  and  routinized  operations — in  office  work,  for  ex- 
ample— any  or  all  of  these  problems  may  well  remain  in  the  supervisor's 
hands  and  demand  therefore  that  he  "know  how."  jie  may  have  to  plan 
the  work,  set  standards  for  quantity  and  quality  of  work  to  be  expected, 
'and  make  specific  assignments  of  duties.  More  will  be  said  in  a  later  section 
about  his  responsibility  for  work  methods.  Safety,  too,  is  a  responsibility 
of_.  the  supervisor.  It  is  his  duty,  often  with  the  help  of  a  specialist— 
the  "safety  engineer" — to  encourage  safe  work  habits,  to  enforce  safety 
rules,  and  otherwise  to  prevent  accident^  A  concomitant  charge  is  to  keep 
the  work  place  clean  and  orderly.  The  supervisor  may  have  to  provide 
workers  with  the  necessary  tools,  equipment,  and  auxiliary  services  such 
as  equipment  maintenance;  or  with  an  adequate  quantity  of  supplies  and 
materials.  Or  his  responsibility  may  be  partial  only,  such  as  the  custody 
of  machines. 

It  follows  that  the  supervisor  must  "know  the  work."  It  does  not  neces- 
sarily follow,  as  is  sometimes  contended,  that  the  supervisor  must  be  an 
expert  in  the  field.  It  is  possible  for  a  good  supervisor  to  move  over  from 
another  type  of  work  and  learn  the  new  work,  especially  when  he  is  picked 
for  his  potential  as  a  supervisor — "a  leader" — rather  than  for  his  expertness 
in  the  work.  This  is  not  as  commonly  done  as  it  should  be,  however.  -* 

Institutional  Aspects.  The  institutional  side  of  the  supervisor's  duties 
involves  the  policies,  procedures,  and  practices  of  his  agency  or  company. 
The  organization  requires  certain  ways  of  doing  things  to  which  the  super- 
visor must  conform.  A  big  chunk  of  this  institutional  responsibility  is  per- 
sonnel policies  and  procedures.  The  supervisor  may  have  authority  to 
select,  place,  and  evaluate  employees,  but  in  actual  practice  any  or  all  of 
these  functions  may  be  carried  on  by  the  personnel  specialist.  The  latter 
arrangement  is  apt  to  be  the  case  in  civil  service  systems.  The  choice  of  a 
worker,  for  example,  may  only  be  in  terms  of  refusing  to  accept  the  worker 
selected  by  others.  In  any  case,  how  the  supervisor  carries  on  these  personnel 
operations  is  usually  prescribed  for  him.  He  merely  needs  to  know  the 
forms  and  procedures,  the  rules  and  regulations,  in  order  to  get  along.  This 
applies  in  particular  to  public  administration.  ^/ 

Such  regulations  may  well  get  in  the  way  of  supervision,  especially 
in  discipline  cases.  Attendance,  punctuality,  and  personal  conduct  on  the 
part  of  the  worker  in  conformity  with  "company  rules"  are  another  branch 
of  "institutionalism"  which  the  supervisor  must  heed.  The  conservation 
and  salvage  of  equipment  and  supplies,  too,  may  be  spelled  out  in  regula- 


424  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

dons,  to  give  another  example.  From  this  brand  of  supervision  stems  the 
temptation  to  promote  the  worker  who  "knows  the  ropes." 

To  sum  up,  the  supervisor  must  know  the  kind  of  work  that  is  done  by 
his  unit  and  the  policies  and  procedures  of  his  agency.  But  our  interest  lies 
in  the  more  distinctive  phase  of  supervision,  the  human  side.  J 

2.  THE  SUPERVISORY  SKILLS 

Wartime  Innovations.  The  supervisor's  skills  have  been  variously  enu- 
merated. One  such  listing  runs  as  long  as  seventeen  essential  skills.  There 
is  no  magic  number.  During  the  great  effort  of  World  War  II,  when  there 
was  heavy  pressure  on  learning  fast,  the  essentials  were  stripped  down  to  a 
minimum  of  three:  JIT,  JMT,  and  JRT.  We  refer  to  the  Training  Within 
Industry  program  of  the  War  Manpower  Commission3  whereby  not  thou- 
sands but  literally  hundreds  of  thousands  of  foremen  were  trained  in  three 
basic  supervisory  skills:  Job  Instruction  Training;  Job  Management  Train- 
ing; and  Job  Relations  Training.  In  other  words,  this  program  was  based 
on .  the -assumption,  jhat  the  irreducible  IT  minium  of  supervisory  skills  is 
three:  (1)  to  instruct  a  worker  how  to  do  a  job;  (2)  to  lay  out  methods 
and  improve  work  processes;  and  (3)  to  deal  personally  with  workers, 
especially  face-to-face. 

The  tripartite  classification  goes  back  quite  some  years  in  history — to 
World  War  I,  in  fact.  At  that  time  the  tremendous  expansion  of  industry 
forced  management  to  pay  attention  to  training  of  supervisors.  Stimulated 
by  the  critical  need  for  quickly  developing  competent  supervisors  for  the 
mushroom  growth  of  plants,  management  experts  made  remarkable  prog- 
ress in  isolating  the  factors  that  make  for  a  good  supervisor,  analyzing  these 
factors,  and  formulating  practical  methods  for  putting  their  findings  into 
practice.  The  wartime  program  resulted  in  continued  study  and  proved 
itself  so  well  in  the  following  years  that  the  emergency  of  World  War  II 
found  us  in  possession  of  tested  methods  for  training  employees  in  the 
skills  of  supervision. 

The  Training  Within  Industry  Service  of  the  War  Manpower  Commis- 
sion, headed  by  industrial  experts  of  long  experience,  launched  a  nation- 
wide program  to  assist  industry  to  meet  the  problems  arising  from  its 
enormous  demand  for  supervisory  personnel.  Thousands  of  factories  and 
offices  throughout  the  country  installed  TWI's  short  intensive  programs 
for  job  instruction,  job  methods,  and  job  relations,  so  that  in  the  end  well 
over  a  million  supervisors  in  war  production  had  gone  through  one  or 
more  of  these  training  programs. 

Numbers  of  participants,  of  course,  prove  nothing.  But  startling  results 
were  achieved  from  this  emphasis  on  the  skills  of  supervision.  Two  out  of 

3  An  excellent  account  of  this  program  is  offered  in  War  Manpower  Commission,  Bureau 
of  Training,  Training  Within  Industry  Service,  The  Training  Within  Industry  Report,  1940- 
1945,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1945. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  425 

every  three  plants  served  by  TWI  reported  production  increases  up  to  25 
per  cent,  and  the  other  third  found  that  better  supervision  raised  output 
from  25  to  500  per  cent.  Comparable  savings  in  manpower  and  time  needed 
to  break  in  new  workers,  in  scrap  and  waste  cost,  and  in  reduction  of  acci- 
dents were  reported.  In  some  plants  absenteeism  was  cut  in  half.  There 
was  also  a  constant  decrease  in  the  rate  of  turnover  among  employees 
whose  supervisors  had  had  the  benefit  of  the  "J"  programs. 

It  was  understandable  that  government  agencies,  experiencing  similar 
expansion,  should  have  looked  with  interest  at  the  successful  attack  industry 
was  making  on  one  of  its  most  critical  personnel  problems.  Experiments 
were  carried  out  to  determine  whether  TWI's  program,  designed  for  in- 
dustrial organizations,  would  be  equally  effective  in  government  agencies 
beset  by  many  of  the  same  manpower  difficulties.  The  answer  was  quickly 
forthcoming.  Although  the  work,  the  operation,  and  the  environment  may 
vary  widely,  the  skills  involved  in  supervising  jobs  are  identical  in  any 
supervisor-and-employee  situation.  Certain  adaptations  had  to  be  made, 
for  the  terminology  and  approach  required  in  government  offices  are  dif- 
ferent from  those  encountered  in  a  machine  shop.  However,  the  alterations 
necessary  were  limited  to  details. 

In  order  to  make  the  TWI  formula  available  to  federal  agencies,  the 
United  States  Civil  Service  Commission  established  a  program  of  training 
and  staffed  it  with  men  and  women  who  could  administer  the  techniques 
that  had  proved  to  be  so  successful  in  industry.  One  further  step  was  taken. 
Instead  of  relieving  office  managers  of  the  responsibility  of  training  their 
supervisors  by  having  outsiders  do  it,  the  emphasis  was  squarely  placed  on 
management's  concern  with  the  training  activity  through  use  of  its  own 
personnel. 

The  general  procedure  was  for  the  Civil  Service  Commission  to  show 
the  individual  government  agency  how  to  train  its  supervisors  and  to  help 
it  follow  through  in  order  to  make  sure  that  the  training  courses  produced 
the  practical  results  that  were  expected.  This  was  done  by  assuring  thai 
the  agency's  top  executive  fully  understood  the  program  and  really  accepted 
the  responsibility  for  its  operation,  and  then  by  giving  selected  agency 
personnel  an  intensive  training  course  to  prepare  them  in  the  techniques 
of  administration.  Three  separate  programs  were  offered  to  the  federa 
agencies.  Each  program  was  drawn  up  to  cover  a  specific  phase  of  super 
vision,  and  each  was  presented  in  five  concentrated  two-hour  sessions.  Since 
the  programs  in  order  to  stand  up  had  to  appeal  to  operating  people  or 
all  levels  and  show  a  direct  application  to  their  own  jobs,  the  whole  ap 
proach  was  specifically  designed  to  get  immediate  action  and  to  accomplisl 
quick  results.  Because  of  the  careful  trial-and-error  development  of  the  pro 
grams  under  actual  operating  conditions,  they  soon  became  streamlined  t< 
the  point  where  they  were  easy  to  understand,  easy  to  present,  easy  to  con 
duct  and  interesting  in  form  and  content. 


426  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

By  examining  the  essentials  of  these  programs  more  closely,  we  can  best 
identify  the  basic  supervisory  skills  in  a  setting  both  concrete  and  generally 
significant.  The  point  that  should  be  kept  in  mind  is  not  the  particular  fea- 
tures of  each  program,  but  the  light  it  sheds  on  the  role  of  ^PeTsupervisor 
From  this  angle,  the  wartime  experience  is  of  lasting  interest.  ^ 

Job  Instruction.  The  expansion  of  public  administration  caused  by^the 
war  dictated  the  firsf^progrnnrf  of  thfs  series  —  teaching  supervisors  how  to 
teach.  With  new  workers  pouring  by  the  thousands  into  govenrment 
offices  and  with  old  workers  assigned  new  duties,  it  was  essential  to  shorten 
as  much  as  possible  the  time  necessary  for  all  these  employees  to  learn 
their  new  jobs.  Managing  an  organization  under  emergency  conditions  is 
a  process  of  constant  adjustment  to  change.  Every  rhangg_flf 


sonnel  calls  for  instructions  to  get  the  work-out  on  time^and,p_laces  a  heavy 
load  on  the  first-line  supervisor.  He  cannot  carry  it  unless  he  has  com- 
petent workers  under  him  who  understand  their  jobs,  know  what  to  do, 

tv  to  do  it,  and  learn  new  jobs  without  time  wasted  or  delay. 
Job-instruction  training  shows  the  supervisor  how  to  teach  those  under 
him  to  perform  their  daily  operations./  The  supervisor,  of  course,  has  always 
done  this,  after  a  fashion.  He  usually  realizes  that  the  new  employee  has 
to  know  something  about  the  job  before  he  can  go  to  work.  So  he  may 
turn  him  over  to  one  of  the  old  hands  for  a  while,  or  he  may  make  an 
effort  to  train  the  neophyte  by  such  means  as  he  is  familiar  with,  and  per- 
haps fail  because  his  methods  are  ineffectual.  If  he  does  nothing  else,  he  at 
least  takes  it  for  granted  that  his  new  employees  will  require  a  certain 
amount  of  time  to  take  hold  of  their  jobs,  and  resigns  himself  to  waiting  for 
the  breaking-in  period  to  end.  Supervisors  who  have  taken  job-instruction 
training  have  learned  that  a  simple  four-step  teaching  method  on  the  job 
is  far  superior  to  the  casual  methods  of  old  which  wasted  so  much  valuable 
time. 

^The  supervisor  is  shown  how  to  explain  a  new  job  to  an  employee,  how 
to  demonstrate  it  so  that  the  employee  can  follow  each  step,  and  how  to 
coach  the  employee  while  he  practices  the  operation  until  it  is  mastered.  He 
is  shown  how  to  guard  against  the  mistake  of  trying  to  give  the  employee 
more  than  he  can  absorb  at  a  time.  VHe  is  also  taught  to  avoid  technical 
language  that  the  learner  cannot  comprehend.  He  is  shown  how  to  discover 
the  parts  of  the  job  that  the  learner  needs  to  know  first.  The  supervisor 
knows  that  merely  telling  a  worker  what  to  do  is  not  enough,  nor  is  it 
enough  to  show  him  how  to  do  it.  He  comes  to  see  the  truth  of  the  training 
slogan:  "If  the  employee  hasn't  learned,  the  supervisor  hasn't  taught."  •** 
Job-instruction  training  brings  together  two  phases  of  the  training 
process:  how  to  get  ready  to  instruct,  and  how  to  instruct.  In  the  first  phase, 
the  supervisor  learns  to  look  at  the  job  analytically,  to  break  it  down  into 
units,  and  to  arrange  the  units  into  a  logical  learning  order.  In  the  second 
phase,  he  learns  exactly  how  to  get  his  knowledge  across  to  the  employee 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  427 

so  that  the  latter  understands  the  job  and  gets  his  work  done  quickly, 
correctly,  and  conscientiously. 

How  to  get  ready  to  instruct  consists  of  the  following  steps:  (1)  have 
a  timetable,  know  how  much  skill  you  expect  to  develop  in  the  worker  and 
how  soon;  (2)  break  down  the  job,  list  the  principal  steps,  pick  out  the  key 
points;  (3)  have  everything  right— tools,  equipment,  and  materials;  and 
(4)  have  the  work  place  properly  arranged,  just  as  the  worker  will  be 
expected  to  keep  it. 
/How  to  instruct  is  also  broken  down  into  four  steps: 

(1)  Prepare  the  worker  by  putting  him  at  his  ease,  finding  out  what  he 
knows  about  the  job,  getting  him  interested  in  learning  and  placing  him 
in  the  correct  position; 

(2)  Present  the  operation  by  telling,  showing,  illustrating,  and  question- 
ing carefully  and  patiently,  stressing  key  points,  and  instructing  clearly  and 
completely,  taking  up  one  point  at  a  time,  but  no  more  than  the  worker 
can  master; 

(3)  Try  out  his  performance  by  testing  him  on  the  job,  having  him  tell 
and  show  you,  and  having  him  explain  key  points  while  you  ask  questions 
and  correct  errors  until  you  tyiow  he  knows;  and 

(4)  Follow  up  by  putting  him  on  his  own,  checking  him  frequently, 
designating  one  to  whom  he  goes  for  help,  encouraging  him  to  ask  questions, 
getting  him  to  look  for  key  points  as  he  progresses,  and  tapering  off 
coaching  and  close  follow-up  as  his  work  improves. 

The  basic  content  of  this  program  is  epitomized  in  simple  terms  on 
a  little  card  furnished  every  supervisor  who  goes  through  it.  However, 
the  method  of  teaching  JIT  is  as  important  as  the  content.  Teaching  JIT 
is  made  up  of  five  closely  packed  two-hour  sessions,  conducted  by  agency 
personnel  that  has  been  previously  trained  by  the  Civil  Service  Commis- 
sion. It  has  been  found  that  best  njfiults  are  obtained  with  groups  of  ten 
or  twelve  participants.  Beyond  that\ujnber  there  is  insufficient  time  for 
individual  practice,  and  JIT  devotes  bVv  little  time  to  theory  and  a  great 
deal  to  application.  Only  the  first  sessions  g^ven  over  to  theoretical  study. 
The  other  four  two-hour  sessions  provide\ach  member  of  the  group  with 
at  least  two  opportunities  to  try  his  hand  at  thfc,  skill  of  instruction  and 
to  benefit  from  the  criticism  of  the  instructor  and  the  olSfcr  members. 

In  short,  each  member  of  the  group  takes  his  turn  in  presenting  an 
actual  demonstration  of  the  method,  using  a  job  operation  employed  in  his 
own  office.  Before  he  can  do  this,  of  course,  he  must  break  down  the  job 
into  a  sequence  of  steps  and  decide  what  key  points  the  learner  must  know 
about.  In  the  demonstration  before  the  group  he  uses  the  job  breakdown 
he  himself  prepared,  and  follows  the  four-step  method  to  instruct  another 
member  who  acts  as  a  learner.  The  group  then  discusses  the  demonstration, 
criticizes  the  presentation,  and  suggests  improvements. 

In  other  words,  the  program  applies  to  the  teaching  method  its  own 


428  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

principles  of  telling  and  showing  the  learner  what  he  is  expected  to  learn, 
giving  him  a  chance  of  actually  trying  it,  and  demonstrating  where  he  suc- 
ceeded and  where  he  failed.  The  final  step  of  following  up  after  the 
supervisor  has  had  opportunity  to  practice  takes  place  later  when  he  has 
returned  to  his  unit  and  has  applied  the  method  on  the  job.  Continued 
emphasis  was  maintained  in  the  form  of  personal  calls  from  representatives 
of  the  Civil  Service  Commission  and  agency  trainers,  presentation  of  illus- 
trative movies  through  the  Office  of  Education  and  other  devices.4 
/  Improving  Methods.  Perhaps  the  strongest  single  impediment  to  man- 
agement progress  is  the  dead  weight  of  tradition — the  habit  of  doing  things 
the  way  they  have  always  been  done.  Habits  are  powerful  and  the  habitual 
method  may  survive  simply  because  we  are  used  to  it,  not  because  it  is  the 
best  method.  The  only  way  organizations  can  rid  themselves  of  outmoded 
procedures,  unnecessary  operations,  and  wasteful  duplications  of  effort  is 
to  subject  every  activity  periodically  to  searching  reexamination.  ^ 

Job  Method  Training  was  evolved  to  meet  the  need  of  supervisors  for 
a  simple,  practical  way  of  improving  jobs — a  plan  they  could  apply  to  their 
daily  work.  Although  originally  developed  by  TWI  for  foremen  in  indus- 
try, its  approach  to  the  integration  of  manpower,  materials,  and  machinery 
is  common  to  all  supervisory  jobs.  The  program  has  been  found  to  be 
readily  adaptable  to  conditions  of  government  work. 

JMT  does  not  make  methods  engineers,  nor  is  it  intended  to  do  so.  It 
does  put  into  the  supervisor's  hands  a  tool  that  will  enable  him  to  examine 
operations  critically  and  to  work  out  improvements  logically  and  effectively. 
The  entire  emphasis  is  on  making  improvements,  not  on  theory  or  mere 
discussion.  (After  being  given  a  sound  conception  of  the  methods  as  applied 
'(to  an  actual  operation,  each  supervisor  is  required  to  analyze  a  job  in  his 
jown  unit  and  to  make  concrete  recommendations  for  changing  the  job  to 
bring  about  more  effective  use  of  manpower,  materials,  and  equipment. 
Each  supervisor  demonstrates  how  he  analyzed  the  present  operation  and 
questioned  every  detail.  He  then  explains  the  new  method  he  has  developed 
in  which  he  eliminates  unnecessary  operations,  and  combines,  rearranges,  and 
simplifies  the  details  to  make  the  job  easier,  faster,  and  more  economical. 

As  in  the  case  of  JIT,  job-methods  training  is  given  to  equally  small 
groups  of  supervisors  in  five  two-hour  sessions.  Again,  the  program  is 
conducted  by  leaders  selected  from  the  agency  personnel  trained  by  the 
Civil  Service  Commission.  The  objective  is  not  to  get  a  certain  number 
of  improvements  from  each  supervisor,  but  to  encourage  a  constant  reap- 
praisal of  existing  methods. 

JMT  can  be  articulated  with  employee-suggestion  systems,  with  employee 
"councils,"  and  with  agency  planning  and  procedure  work.  It  stimulates  a 
constant  flow  of  ideas  for  new  and  better  ways  of  doing  old  jobs. 

4C/.  United  States  Civil  Service  Commission,  Supervision  Improvement  Program,  A  Pro* 
gram  for  Supervisors  in  the  Federal  Service,  Washington,  1943. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  429 

The  great  virtue  of  JMT  is  that  it  opens  up  to  every  supervisor  the 
opportunity  to  be  creative  about  his  work.  The  success  of  this  program 
affords  new  evidence  that  there  is  in  each  of  us  a  creative  imagination  at 
work  that  speculates  on  the  possibility  of  making  changes  in  the  established 
scheme  of  things,  even  in  matters  that  are  not  in  our  own  immediate 
province.  In  this  natural  tendency  of  human  beings  we  possess  an  inex- 
haustible spring  of  improvement  possibilities  that  is  virtually  untapped.  Al- 
though management  recognizes  the  necessity  for  revising  its  procedures  to 
effect  modifications  and  short-cuts,  too  often  it  turns  this  task  over  to  special- 
ized planning  staffs  or  method  engineers,  without  using  the  potential  flow  of 
ideas  that  could  come  from  the  mass  of  employees  on  the  job. 

First-line  supervisors  are  in  a  key  position  to  carry  out  management 
policy.  They  work  closely  with  employees  in  the  details  of  processes  and 
projects,  and  have  intimate  knowledge  of  a  multitude  of  operations  that  in 
the  aggregate  make  up  the  program  of  the  agency.  In  fact,  many  times 
the  supervisor  is  the  only  manager  and  representative  of  management  who 
knows  enough  about  the  technical  aspects  of  his  unit  to  make  intelligent 
comments  about  it.  Consequently,  management  is  incapable  of  streamlining 
the  totality  of  jobs  in  the  organization  without  the  vigorous  assistance  of 
the  supervisor. 

Here  is  the  way  the  little  card  that  is  handed  to  all  supervisors  who  take 
JM3& describes  the  essence  of  this  approach: 

Step  1.  Brea^  down  the  job.  (a)  List  all  details  of  a  job  exactly 
as  it  is  done  by  the  present  method,  (b)  Be  sure  details  include  every- 
thing you  and  others  do  in  using  (1)  manpower,  (2)  materials,  (3) 
equipment. 

Step  2.  Question  every  detail,  (a)  Use  these  types  of  questions:  (1) 
Why  is  it  necessary?  (2)  What  is  its  purpose?  (3)  Where  should  it 
be  done?  (4)  When  should  it  be  done?  (5)  Who  should  do  it? 
(6)  How  is  the  best  way  to  do  it?  (b)  Also  question  the  office  lay-out, 
work  places,  flow  of  work,  safety,  forms,  form  letters,  clearances,  review- 
ing, and  all  other  procedures. 

Step  3.  Develop  the  new  method,  (a)  Eliminate  unnecessary  detail, 
(b)  Combine  details  when  practical,  (c)  Rearrange  for  better  sequence, 
(d)  Simplify  all  unnecessary  detail.  (1)  To  make  the  work  easier: 
(A)  Pre-position  materials,  supplies,  and  equipment  at  the  best  places 
in  the  proper  work  areas.  (B)  Let  both  hands  do  useful  work.  (C) 
Use  devices  for  materials.  (D)  Work  out  your  idea  with  others.  (E) 
Write  up  your  proposed  method. 

Step  4.  Apply  the  new  method,  (a)  Sell  your  proposal  to  your  boss, 
(b)  Sell  the  new  method  to  the  employees,  (c)  Get  approvals  from  all 
concerned,  (d)  Put  the  new  method  to  work,  use  it  until  a  better  is 
developed,  (e)  Give  credit  where  credit  is  due. 

J^b^methods.-training  has  had  such  an  immediate  positive  effect  on  the 
attitude  of  supervisors  toward  their  own  jobs  that  some  agencies  have  tried 
to  carry  the^  idea  one  step  further—to  the  individual  employeie^  The  result 


430  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

has  been  gratifying.  Besides  demonstrating  that  the  program  is  easily  within 
the  capacity  of  the  average  employee,  such  extension  gives  recognition  to 
one  factor  that  is  essential  to  this  type  of  training.  Both  the  employee  and 
the  supervisor  must  be  made  to  see  that  suggestions  from  them  are  sincerely 
desired  by  those  higher  up.  Although  each  of  us  thinks  he  knows  how  to 
improve  on  the  established  way  of  doing  things,  we  have  a  natural  reluc- 
tance about  appearing  to  criticize  our  superiors.  It's  different  when  we  are 
asked  to  give  constructive  criticism. 

Wording  with  People.  For  many  supervisors,  the  most  difficult  part  of 
their  job  is  acquiring  the  knack  of  dealing  with  employees.  This  ability 
is  vital  to  good  supervision  for  every  act  of  the  supervisor  has  a  bearing 
one  way  or  the  other  on  the  attitude  and  morale  of  employees.  Supervisors 
do  not  need  an  elaborate  course  in  applied  psychology  to  develop  the  skill 
required  to  get  results  through  other  people,  but  they  do  need  an  under- 
standing of  the  fundamentals  which  lie  behind  employee  attitudes  and  a 
workable  method  of  applying  those  fundamentals. 

Job-relations  training  is  concerned  with  two  phases  of  the  supervisor's 
problem.  The  first  is  the  general  knowledge  essential  to  dealing  with  all 
employees,  the  "foundation  of  good  relations."  The  basic  principles  are 
few:  tell  employees  how  they  are  getting  along;  give  credit  where  it  is  due; 
make  the  most  of  each  person's  ability;  and  inform  employees  of  changes 
that  affect  them.  The  second  phase  deals  with  the  technique  of  handling 
individual  problems — the  special  problems  that  arise  because  employees  are 
not  a  "great  grey  mass"  but  individuals,  each  with  his  own  reactions, 
emotions,  backgrounds,  and  abilities. 

The  training  methods,  however,  are  much  the  same  as  with  JIT  and 
JMT — five  two-hour  sessions,  mostly  taken  up  with  application  to  actual 
situations,  and  led  by  the  agency's  own  personnel  who  have  been  trained 
by  the  Civil  Service  Commission.  First,  the  technique  of  maintaining  good 
relations  is  demonstrated  to  the  group  of  participants,  using  actual  cases 
taken  from  job  situations.  Next,  each  supervisor  brings  in  a  case  from  his 
own  unit  and  presents  an  application  of  the  JRT  method.  The  group  helps 
him  to  establish  what  his  real  objective  is,  what  facts  need  to  be  secured, 
what  possible  actions  he  could  take,  and  the  probable  effect  of  each  action. 

No  final  judgment  is  passed  on  the  supervisor's  solution.  The  purpose 
is  to  give  him  skill  in  arriving  at  decisions,  not  to  hand  him  a  set  of  canned 
decisions.  This  training  supplies  the  supervisor  with  an  understanding  of 
job  attitudes  and  the  methods  of  handling  employee-relation  problems. 
With  this  guidance  each  supervisor  can  develop  his  own  skill  and  feeling 
for  the  human  factor. 

The  core  of  job-relations  training  is  concisely  stated  on  a  small  reference 
card  given  to  trainees: 

Foundations  for  good  relations.    (1)  Let  each  worker  know  how  he 
is  getting  along,  (a)  Figure  out  what  you  expect  from  him.  (b)  Point 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  431 

out  to  him  ways  to  improve.  (2)  Give  credit  when  due.  (a)  Recognize 
extra  or  unusual  performance,  (b)  Tell  him  when  it  is  fresh;  tell  him 
while  it  is  fresh.  (3)  Tell  an  employee  in  advance  about  changes  that 
will  affect  him.  (a)  Tell  him  why,  if  possible,  (b)  Get  him  to  accept 
the  change.  (4)  Make  the  best  use  of  each  person's  ability,  (a)  Look 
for  ability  not  now  being  used,  (b)  Never  stand  in  an  employee's  way. 
People  must  be  treated  lil(e  individuals.  How  to  handle  a  problem. 
(1)  Get  the  facts,  (a)  Review  the  record,  (b)  Find  out  what  rules  and 
customs  apply,  (c)  Talk  with  individuals  concerned,  (d)  Get  opinions 
and  feelings,  (e)  Be  sure  that  you  have  the  whole  story.  (2)  Weigh 
and  decide,  (a)  Fit  the  facts  together,  (b)  Consider  their  bearing  on 
each  other,  (c)  Check  practices  and  policies,  (d)  What  possible  actions 
are  there?  (e)  Consider  effect  on  individual,  group,  and  production. 
(f)  Don't  jump  to  conclusions.  (3)  Take  action,  (a)  Can  you  handle 
this  yourself?  (b)  Do  you  need  help  in  handling  it?  (c)  Should  you 
refer  this  to  your  supervisor?  (d)  Time  your  action  properly,  (e)  Don't 
pass  the  buck.  (4)  Check  results,  (a)  How  soon  will  you  follow-up?  (b) 
How  often  will  you  need  to  check?  (c)  Watch  for  changes  in  output, 
attitudes  and  relationships,  (d)  Did  your  action  help  production? 

Of  course,  no  matter  how  well  the  supervisor  masters  these  points,  he  still 
has  to  be  JJroficient  in  the  art  of  leadership.  Perhaps  an  outstanding  leader 
must  be  born,  but  certainly  skill  in  leadership  can  be  improved,  as  job- 
relations  training  has  demonstrated.  Application  of  fundamental  proposi- 
tions does  have  an  important  bearing  on  human  relations  on  the  job. 

One  fundamental  fact  is  that  we  are  all  different.  Each  one  of  us  brings 
to  a  job  his  own  individual  attitudes,  his  hopes  and  ambitions,  his  aptitudes 
and  his  interests.  A  given  situation  will  affect  each  individual  according 
to  his  own  point  of  view,  and  it  may  affect  him  in  an  entirely  different 
way  on  another  occasion.  Furthermore,  all  of  us  have  other  things  burden- 
ing us  besides  our  jobs,  which  can  very  well  interfere  with  our  state  of 
mind — our  health,  our  family,  our  future  security,  to  name  but  a  few. 
These  factors  may  exist  in  many  different  combinations.  Any  approach 
to  the  problems  arising  out  of  human  relationships  must  inevitably  be  made 
on  the  basis  of  the  individual  case. 

It  is  not  necessary  to  turn  supervisors  into  trained  psychologists  to  help 
them  deal  with  their  employees  as  individuals.  The  average  supervisor, 
impressed  with  the  policy  of  treating  everybody  alike  and  given  a  tech- 
nique of  unearthing  the  facts  underlying  employee  attitudes,  will  make 
sound  or  at  least  sounder  decisions.  If  he  uses  job-relations  techniques,  his 
decisions  will  be  sounder  because  he  will  try  to  learn  all  the  facts  in  each 
case — not  merely  those  that  appear  on  the  surface — and  because  he  will  not 
consider  the  case  closed  until  the  decision  has  been  proven  to  be  correct. 

It  is  plain  that  the  highly  condensed  solutions  into  which  JIT,  JMT, 
and  JRT  have  been  put  are  by  themselves  mcrcly^ghots  in  the  arm.  The 
supervisor,  to  be  effectively  trained,  must  be  provided  with  a  plan  for  de- 
veloping skill  on  the  job.  Therefore  follow-up  is  highly  important.  Con- 


432  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

tinucd  use  and  perfection  of  the  three  skills  must  be  the  watchword  if  the 
supervisor  is  to  become  adept  at  his  trade. 

Finally,  management  must  accept  the  implications  of  this  kind  of  train- 
ing  by  reexamining  its  policies  and  operations  to  see  if  they  conflict  with 
the  basic  propositions  which  the  first-line  supervisor  is  expected  to  follow. 
For  example,  it  is  unreasonable  to  hope  that  a  supervisor  will  maintain 
much  enthusiasm  for  improving  job  methods  in  the  face  of  hostility  of  his 
own  supervisor  every  time  he  makes  a  suggestion.  A  supervisor  will  not  be 
convinced  very  long  that  his  superiors  sincerely  want  to  treat  employees 
fairly  and  intelligently,  if  he  himself  is  suffering  from  unfair  or  unintelli- 
gent treatment.  He  will  relax  his  efforts  if  his  superiors  violate  principles 
of  good  employee  relations  in  formulating  or  enforcing  personnel  policies. 
Again,  the  supervisor  may  become  fully  convinced  in  the  JIT  program  that 
part  of  his  job  is  to  improve  his  employees'  efficiency  through  continued 
training  on  the  job,  but  this  conviction  will  not  be  sustained  if  no  continued 
interest  is  taken  higher  up  in  his  own  improvement.  This  is  another  way 
of  saying  that  the  new  programs,  although  they  are  designed  primarily  for 
first-line  supervisors,  enunciate  conceptions  that  are  applicable  anywhere  in 
the  organizational  hierarchy  right  up  to  the  head  of  the  agency. 

It  should  be  pointed  out  that  all  of  the  three  J  programs  were  utilized 
not  only  by  the  federal  government  but  by  states,  counties,  and  cities  as  well. 
Many  of  these  took  advantage  of  the  TWI  trainers  to  secure  supervisory  in- 
struction within  their  own  jurisdictions.  Others  used  the  materials  as  devel- 
oped by  the  work-improvement  program  of  the  United  States  Civil  Service 
Commission. 

Worf^  Simplification.  Let  us  now  turn  to  a  related  effort,  the  so-called 
work-simplification  program  developed  by  the  United  States  Bureau  of  the 
Budget.5  As  in  the  case  of  job-methods  training  under  TWI,  this  is  an 
attempt  to  condense  training  into  a  readily  understandable  form,  which  can 
be  easily  assimilated  by  first-line  supervisors  themselves.  It  should  not  be 
inferred  that  the  work-simplification  program  duplicates  job-methods  train- 
ing; it  is  a  more  specific  though  highly  simplified  program  in  itself. 

It  is  built  around  three  basic  management  problems:  (1)  the  distribu- 
tion of  work;  (2)  the  sequence  of  work;  and  (3)  the  volume  of  work. 
For  these  three  basic  problems  there  are  three  elementary  tools  to  be  used: 
(1)  the  work-distribution  chart;  (2)  the  process  chart;  and  (3)  the  work 
count.  The  supervisor  is  trained  in  the  use  of  the  three  tools  in  order  that 
he  may  be  able  to  solve  each  respective  basic  problem. 

The  method  is  equally  interesting.    The  first  training  session  is  given 

5  Cf.  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Trainer's  Guide  to  the  Wor%  Simplification 
Training  Sessions;  Specifications  for  Agency  Wor\  Simplification;  Supervisor's  Guide  to  the 
Work,.  Distribution  Chart;  Supervisor's  Guide  to  the  Process  Chart;  Supervisor's  Guide  to  the 
Wor\  Count ,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1945.  The  essence  of  these  materials 
is  also  available  in  Publication  No.  91,  Public  Administration  Service,  Chicago,  1945. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  433 

over  to  introducing  the  program,  setting  up  the  objectives  of  the  sessions, 
and  getting  the  group  to  know  each  other.  About  an  hour  is  devoted  to 
discussing  the  work-distribution  chart.  This  is  the  preface,  so  to  speak, 
:o  two  hours  of  "laboratory"  work  in  which  the  supervisor  himself  uses 
the  work-distribution  chart.  The  second  session  reviews  the  work  performed 
and  introduces  the  process  chart.  This  again  is  followed  by  "laboratory" 
activity  in  which  the  supervisors  meet  with  the  instructor  to  make  up  their 
first  process  chart.  The  third  training  session  in  a  similar  fashion  deals 
with  the  work  count,  followed  once  more  by  individual  application.  The 
instructor  makes  an  appointment  with  each  supervisor,  meets  him  at  his 
desk,  and  helps  to  determine  what  work  to  count  in  his  own  unit.  Then 
there  is  a  final  session  of  three  hours  in  which  the  total  program  is  reviewed 
and  supervisors  demonstrate  their  competence  in  using  the  three  tools.  As 
in  the  case  of  the  J  programs,  follow-up  is  indispensable. 

All  of  this  merely  draws  additional  emphasis  to  the  supervisor's  task 
of  dealing  with  his  people — the  crux  of  the  whole  supervisory  situation. 
No  supervisor  can  hope  to  be  successful  unless  he  learns  to  lead  without 
bossing.  The  days  of  the  "straw  boss"  who  shouted  his  orders  and  cracked 
his  whip  are  over.  It  never  was  an  effective  method,  even  before  the  ad- 
vent of  a  more  mature  appreciation  of  work  democracy  and  organized 
labor.  The  secret  of  good  supervision  is  to  suggest,  to  stimulate  with  a 
word  of  praise,  to  lead  by  example. 

Much  of  the  supervisor's  task  is  to  work  with  the  employees  he  has. 
He  might  sometimes  wish  he  could  fire  all  of  his  workers  and  replace  them 
with  abler  ones.  This  is  seldom  possible  or  desirable.  Therefore,  one  of 
the  tricks  in  the  supervisor's  bag  must  be  to  know  how  to  develop  hidden 
ability.  Realistically,  of  course,  it  is  no  trick  at  all;  it  is  a  competence 
gained  only  from  study  and  association  with  the  worker,  from  understand- 
ing his  whole  attitude,  and  from  willingness  to  help  him.  As  in  leading 
without  bossing,  discovering  hidden  abilities  requires  going  to  the  worker, 
being  sympathetic,  studying  him  carefully,  and  giving  him  every  oppor- 
tunity to  express  himself.  This  same  basic  approach  will  also  create  a 
favorable  working  climate,  in  which  the  worker  will  have  a  feeling  of  re- 
lease and  not  a  feeling  of  repression. 

The  discussion  so  far  may  suggest  that  the  supervisor  has  a  gigantic 
job  which  he  does  all  alone.  This,  of  course,  would  not  be  true,  particu- 
larly in  government.  In  instructional  situations — in  handling  the  problems 
of  teaching  workers  new  tasks,  new  methods,  and  new  procedures— the 
supervisor,  in  almost  all  governmental  jurisdictions,  has  the  help  of  a  train- 
ing officer  or  a  training  division.^  This  is  also  true  of  his  general  handling 
of  personnel  matters.  In  fact,  most  of  these  things  are  done  for  him  by  a 
recruiting  officer,  an  employment  officer,  and  other  specialists.  Likewise, 
when  it  comes  to  methods,  the  planning  staff  of  the  agency  is  generally 
at  hand,  often  stimulating  the  supervisor  to  develop  new  work  procedures 


434  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

and  improve  old  methods.  On  morale  problems  and  on  handling  out-of- 
the-ordinary  cases,  the  supervisor  in  many  governmental  jurisdictions  has 
the  help  of  an  employee  counselor  or  employee-relations  officer.  However, 
the  emphasis  must  be  constantly  maintained  that  in  the  concrete  situatior 
these  functions  are  all  those  of  the  supervisor.  Even  if  he  receives  help 
from  above,  the  burden  inevitably  continues  to  be  his. 

3.  PROBLEMS  OF  SUPERVISION 

V 

There  is  a  temptation  to  capsulate  and  reduce  to  catchwords  and  slogans 

the  truths  that  should  govern  supervision  in  order  that  a  working  tech- 
nique may  be  applied.  Slogans  can  be  coined,  but  they  may  be  misunder- 
stood. What  is  good  supervision?  What  should  the  qualities  of  a  super- 
visor be  in  order  to  make  him  effective? 

Variations  in  Supervisory  Situations.  In  a  still-unpublished  monograph 
entitled  Introduction  to  Supervision?  John  M.  Pfiffner  has  offered  an  ex- 
cellent analysis  to  answer  these  two  questions.  Any  answer  must  allow  for 
many  variations.  In  the  first  place,  what  makes  for  effective  supervision 
in  situations  dealing  with  one  kind  of  work  may  not  do  so  under  other 
conditions.  Supervising  miners  is  a  task  different  from  supervising  typists 
in  a  stenographic  pool,  not  to  mention  supervising  scientists  in  a  laboratory. 
Secondly,  and  as  a  corollary,  the^ingredients  of  good  supervision  will  vary 
i  with  the  kind  of  people  involved.  Highly  skilled  artisans  or  highly  edu- 
cated professional  employees  may  be  of  prima  dbfl/zfl  "'temperament  and 
demand  an  entirely  different  kind  of  attention  than  less  skilled  or  trained 
individuals.  Thirdly,  the  concrete  work  situation  may  make  a  substantial 
difference.  Work  in  an  office  requires  one  pattern  of  supervisory  knowledge 
and  skills;  work  in  a  factory,  in  a  commercial  establishment,  or  in  a  school 
building  requires  another. 

Fourth,  the  extent  of  supervisory  responsibility  will  have  a  good  deal 
to  do  with  the  demands  made  on  the  supervisor.  The  supervisor  whose 
range  of  duties  is  narrow  probably  need  not  be  as  specifically  qualified  as 
the  supervisor  whose  responsibilities  are  comprehensive  in  terms  of  the 
work  of  his  unit.  The  supervisor  who  is  bolstered  by  a  training  assistant, 
personnel  officer,  and  employee  counselor  probably  need  not  be  as  broadly 
trained  as  one  who  has  to  work  completely  on  his  own,  without  staff 
services.  Or,  the  supervisor  who  makes  important  decisions  as  to  what  work 
has  to  be  done  and  how  it  is  to  be  done  will  need  to  be  a  more  highly 
competent  individual.  Fifth,  the  level  of  supervision  is  important?  The  first- 
line  supervisor  will  undoubtedly  have  less  need  for  intellectual  powers  than 
the  supervisor  much  further  up  the  line.  The  former  will  have  more  need 
for  detailed  knowledge  of  the  work  to  be  done. 

« Pfiffner,  John  M.,  Introduction  to  Supervision,  University  of  Southern  California,  Los 
Angeles,  1944,  mimeographed. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  435 

Requirements  of  Good  Supervision.  Pfiffncr7  lists  eight  requirements 
of  good  supervision  and  good  supervisors:  (1)  Command  of  job  content; 
(2)  personal  qualifications;  (3)  teaching  ability;  (4)  general  outlook; 
(5)  courage  and  fortitude;  (6)  ethical  and  moral  considerations;  (7)  admin- 
istrative technology;  and  (8)  curiosity  and  intellectual  ability.  To  elaborate: 

(1)  Job  content.  An  expert  knowledge  of  the  work  to  be  done  is  per- 
haps desirable  at  the  first  level  of  supervision,  but  it  is  doubtful  if  it  is 
essential.  Ability  to  do  the  work  skillfully  is  helpful  because  it  enables  the 
supervisor  to  answer  questions  by  his  example.  Furthermore,  it  enables  him 
to  judge  results.  It  helps  him  to  lay  out  work  in  such  a  way  that  one  worker 
is  not  overburdened  and  another  underemployed.   However,  too  great  an 
expertness  in  the  work  is  less  desirable,  especially  if  it  tends  to  make  the 
supervisor  the  best  worker'of  the  unit,  rather  than  its  supervisor. 

It  is  doubtful  whether  supervisors  should  be  recruited  without  regard  to 
their  knowledge  of  the  job  to  be  supervised.  In  many  work  situations,  super- 
visors could  probably  be  given  quick  training  in  the  job  content,  buttthey 
should  still  be  selected  because  of  personal  qualification.  Seniority  alonFlT 
one  of  the  worst  possible  bases  for  picking  supervisors.  Some  one  has  very 
pointedly  remarked  that  twenty  years  of  experience  may  be  simply  one 
year's  experience  repeated  twenty  times.  ) 

(2)  Personal   qualifications.    These   are   probably   the   most  important 
qualifications  for  any  supervisor.  The  best  supervisory  material  comes  from 
among  those  who  like  people,  who  enjoy  cooperating  with  others,  who  have 
the  ability  to  attract  others  to  themselves,  who  can  motivate  them  positively 
and  unite  them  in  their  work.   But  we  must  go  beyond  this  point  to  con- 
siderations of  emotional  stability  and  intellectual  integrity. 

Without  emotional  stability,  the  supervisor  will  not  be  able  to  control 
himself.  If  he  cannot  control  himself  at  all  times,  if  he  is  apt  to  speak  to  an 
employee  in  anger,  he  is  not  a  good  supervisor.  Intellectual  integrity  implies 
an  objective  attitude  which  grows  out  of  a  knowledge  of  one's  strength  and 
weakness.  Such  a  knowledge  permits  the  supervisor  to  be  objective  toward 
others,  especially  in  handling  grievances. 

Along  with  emotional  balance,  there  should  be  balance  in  other  traits  as 
well.  It  seems  fairly  well  established  in  psychological  testing  that  good 
supervisory  material  is  more  dominant  than  recessive,  more  extroverted 
than  introverted,  more  stable  than  unstable,  more  self-sufficient  than  depend- 
ent on  others.  Any  of  these  traits,  however,  when  carried  to  an  extreme 
degree  is  harmful. 

An  individual  who  must  dominate  in  every  situation  certainly  is  not 
good  supervisory  material.  Neither  is  the  individual  who  is  so  completely 
extroverted  that  he  is  not  aware  of  the  reactions  of  others.  He  who  is  so 
well  integrated  and  stable  that  nothing  can  ruffle  him  is  by  that  very  fact 

7  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  6. 


436  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

often  deprived  of  motivating  power  and  of  the  drive  that  may  lead  him  or 
others  far.  Likewise,  the  supervisor  who  carries  self-sufficiency  to  the  ex- 
treme and  never  seeks  advice  from  others  is  apt  to  become  an  autocrat  in 
his  actions.  Finally  getting  down  to  physical  characteristics,  it  certainly  helps 
if  the  supervisor  "cuts  a  good  figure" — if  he  has  the  physical  presence  to 
command  the  attention  of  others.  Of  course,  that  does  not  compensate  for 
personal  weaknesses  within. 

(3)  Teaching  ability.  This  is  one  of  the  three  basic  skills  of  supervision. 
Supervisory  work  requires  the  ability  to  participate  and  lead  in  conferences, 
to  teach  groups  of  individuals.  It  requires  also  the  ability  to  teach  oneself, 
to  keep  perpetually  at  the  process  of  self-education,  to  remain  up-to-date  on 
changes  and  new  developments. 

(4)  General  outlool^.  A  supervisor  needs  to  be  career-minded  if  he  is  to 
set  an  example  to  his  employees.  This,  after  all,  is  the  most  effective  method 
of  leadership.   The  supervisor  should  love  his  job  and  be  absorbed  in  it. 
He  can  then  engender  enthusiasm  in  others  and  stimulate  them  by  his 
own  example.  If  he  is  career-minded,  he  will  foster  what  has  been  called 
"clan  pride"  or  esprit  de  corps,  thus  furnishing  a  subtle  but  effective  motiva- 
tion that  is  an  all-important  morale  factor. 

(5)  Courage  and  fortitude.    These  make  the  supervisor  fully  assume 
responsibility  in  all  cases  where  he  should.  Without  both  he  will  not  have 
>the  stamina  to  take  action  decisively.    He  will  not  be  willing  to  "walk 
toward  danger."  He  may  not  say  "no"  when  he  should,  nor  frankly  con- 
fess mistakes.   However,  boldness  must  be  balanced  with  caution,  bravery 
with  tact;  otherwise  the  supervisor  will  "stick  his  neck  out"  until  someone 
hacks  it  off.  ^ 

(6)  Ethical  and  Moral  Considerations.   It  is  difficult  to  speak  of  these 
without  sounding  like  the  "pulpit,"  yet  they  are  not  trivial.  Whether  it  be 
petty  pilfering  of  the  stamp  box,  abusing  the  expense  account  for  personal 
purposes,  drinking  or  gambling,  being  careless  about  one's  credit  rating, 
piling  up  traffic  offenses,  or  the  wrong  kinds  of  amorous  involvements— any 
of  these  reflects  on  the  respect  and  dignity  which  must  attend  the  supervisor 
if  he  is  to  do  his  best  at  his  job.  Default  in  any  of  such  directions  may  very 
well  impair  the  value  of  his  example.  Supervision  requires  a  natural  assump- 
tion of  responsibility  and  a  natural  desire  to  set  a  good  example. 

(7)  Administrative  technology.  This  refers  to  the  ability  of  the  super- 
visor to  organize  and  coordinate.  The  whole  purpose  of  his  job  existence  is  to 
get  work  done.  If  he  cannot  organize  this  work  and  coordinate  the  efforts 
of  those  who  work  with  him,  he  will  fail  in  supervision.  It  is  therefore  neces- 
sary for  him  to  know  something  about  administration,  to  have  a  sense  of  sys- 
tem and  method.  He  has  to  be  able  to  lay  out  schedules  and  assign  work, 
so  as  to  keep  constant  the  stream  of  production.   He  cannot  get  by  with 
fragmentary  knowledge.  Above  all,  he  should  know  the  place  of  his  unit 
in  the  organization  as  a  whole. 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  437 

(8)  Curiosity  and  intellectual  ability.  The  inquiring  mind  with  an  appe- 
tite for  unsolved  problems  is  at  a  real  premium  in  our  world.  That  is  why 
it  is  necessary  for  the  supervisor  not  to  be  too  much  submerged  in  the  de- 
tails of  the  work  of  his  unit,  why  he  must  be  detached  enough  to  see  the 
problems  beneath  and  to  work  on  them.  Furthermore,  he  needs  to  be  suf- 
ficiently superior  in  intellect  to  be  able  to  have  an  effective  approach  to 
problems  and  to  be  a  good  problem-solver.  He  needs  this  ability  to  separate 
essentials  from  nonessentials.  Certainly  the  supervisor  should  be  capable 
of  making  decisions  in  a  deliberate  manner,  and  not  "by  the  seat  of  his 
pants." 

Democracy  of  Wor\.  Examination  of  these  eight  requirements  shows 
that  the  "spirit  of  supervision"  demands  leadership  rather  than  driving 
force.  The  aim  is  to  secure  a  voluntary  and  spontaneous  work  response, 
with  the  workers  themselves  participating  as  much  as  is  feasible  in  planning 
job  strategy  and  determining  production  methods.  It  has  logically  been 
contended  that  for  organic  progress  the  fundamentals  of  Anglo-Saxon 
political  democracy  and  constitutional  government  should  be  extended  into 
the  manager-worker  relationship. 

In  a  sense,  this  is  the  issue  of  democracy  versus  hierarchy.  In  such  a  dis- 
cussion we  are  inevitably  bucking  the  set  ways  of  thinking  about  superior- 
subordinate  relationships,  about  the  "inefficiency"  of  democracy,  and  about 
the  "command  functions"  in  the  military  sense.  However,  support  is  fur- 
nished by  the  writings  of  Mary  Parker  Follett,8  Elton  Mayo,9  Fritz  J.  Roeth- 
lisberger,10  and  others.11 

Mary  Follett  has  pointed  out  that  the  claims  made  for  final  authority 
are  mostly  based  on  illustion.  True  authority  actually  springs  only  from 
the  intrinsic  competence,  worthiness,  and  strength  of  one  in  a  place  of 
authority.  To  be  called  authority,  it  must  be  spontaneously  and  tacitly 
acquiesced  in  by  the  workers.  Authority  does  not  leap  forth  from  the  com- 
mands of  those  at  the  top  simply  because  the  organization  chart  or  the 
manual  says  so.  It  arises  out  of  "the  law  of  the  situation,"  which  is  the  anti- 
thesis to  the  "illusion  of  final  authority."  In  other  words,  institutional  situa- 
tions demand  certain  actions  to  be  taken  by  those  whom  commonsense  and 
general  agreement  indicate  as  the  ones  to  take  such  actions,  regardless  of 
what  the  hierarchic  lines  might  be. 

This  kind  of  thinking  means,  in  terms  of  effective  supervision,  that  the 
supervisor  must  be  in  part  democratically  chosen.  He  must  command  the 

8  See  her  Dynamic  Administration,  New  York:  Harper,  1942. 

9  See  his  Human  Problems  of  an  Industrial  Civilization,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1933, 
and  Social  Problems  of  an  Industrial  Civilization,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1945. 

10  See  his  Management  and  Morale,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,   1941;  and 
Roethlisberger,  Fritz  J.  and  Dickson,  William  J.,  Management  and  the  Worker.  Cambridge: 
Harvard  University  Press,  1943. 

I1*:/.  Bradford,  Leland  P.  and  Lippitt,  Ronald,  "Building  a  Democratic  Work  Group," 
Personnel,  1945,  Vol.  22,  p.  142  ff. 


438  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

respect  and  the  following  of  his  subordinates.  Otherwise  he  will  be  super- 
visor in  name  only.  He  may  actually  give  the  commands,  but  another 
may  do  the  leading  because  that  other  has  implicit  prestige  with  his  fellows. 
The  effective  supervisor,  by  superior  knowledge  and  greater  skill,  "takes 
the  workers  with  him."  His  use  of  the  power  of  command  is  secondary  at 
best. 

It  is  a  mistake,  however,  to  think  of  hierarchy  and  democracy  as  being 
antithetical.  The  spirit  and  practice  of  supervision  can  be  democratic  with- 
out infringing  upon  the  essentials  of  manual-prescribed  discipline.  Demo- 
cratic supervision  solicits  the  worker's  interest  and  participation  in  the  pro- 
duction process  on  a  consultative  basis.  At  the  same  time,  there  must  be  a 
certain  definiteness  in  the  handling  of  human  situations  and  a  consistency 
with  responsibilities  under  the  laws  and  regulations. 

Fair  dealing  and  justice  sometimes  require  painful  measures  for  the 
good  of  the  employees  themselves.  Likewise  democracy  in  administration,  to 
be  effective,  must  be  able  to  act  expeditiously  when  necessary.  It  cannot  sur- 
vive in  the  ways  of  a  submissive  supervisor  who  does  not  dare  to  take  action 
for  fear  of  worker  resentment.  Neither  can  democratic  administration  exist 
if  the  employees  are  dominated  by  emotional  dread  of  all  authority.  The 
spirit  of  supervision  should  be  democratic,  and  the  supervisor  should  seize 
every  possible  opportunity  to  defer  to  the  essential  dignity  and  the  senti- 
ments of  the  worker.  However,  this  can  never  come  about  on  a  lasting 
basis  unless  the  worker  in  turn  is  mindful  of  his  obligations  as  well  as  his 
rights. 

As  Pfiffner  puts  it:12 

Managers  and  supervisors  must  come  to  the  realization  that  discretion 
and  flexibility  are  not  synonymous  with  arbitrariness  and  power.  Man- 
agement of  the  future,  whether  public  or  private,  must  learn  to  work 
within  the  framework  of  the  new  personnel  jurisprudence,  which  places 
upon  the  supervisory  staff  the  same  type  of  restriction  which  constitu- 
tional safeguards  in  the  Bill  of  Rights  exercise  over  the  executive  officers 
of  government.  It  should  be  remembered  that  the  idea  of  tying  the 
hands  of  kings  with  constitutional  restraint  was  thought  to  be  a  radical 
move  by  the  substantial  people  in  the  world  until  more  modern  times. 
In  the  present  century,  we  have  fought  two  world  wars  to  preserve  con- 
stitutional government  with  its  legal  safeguards  against  governmental 
power  over  individuals.  It  seems  reasonable  to  assume  that  the  same 
type  of  arbitrary  power  of  the  supervisor  over  the  worker  should  be 
abolished  in  favor  of  the  wholesome  discretion  exercised  within  the  limi- 
tations of  a  rapidly  developing  personnel  jurisprudence. 

One  final  note  might  be  added.  It  is  becoming  increasingly  clear  with  the 
rise  of  labor  unions  in  industry  that  the  day  of  democracy  has  not  only 
dawned  but  that  the  sun  is  shining  near  the  zenith.  \  A  highly  placed 
manager  of  one  of  the  country's  biggest  industries  recently  gave  an  amusing 

12  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  6  (by  permission  of  the  author) . 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  439 

illustration  of  what  this  may  mean  in  terms  of  human  relations.  After 
leaving  a  dollar-a-year  job  in  Washington,  he  went  back  to  his  plant  and 
made  a  personal  inspection  trip.  Several  times  he  was  stopped  in  the  corri- 
dors by  groups  of  workers  lounging  and  smoking.  He  could  not  tell 
whether  they  were  on  a  regular  recess  or  not.  Nevertheless,  he  had  to  say 
"pardon  me"  and  "excuse  me"  in  order  to  proceed  through  the  corridors, 
whereas  a  few  years  ago — he  said — he  would  have  taken  the  names  and 
numbers  of  each  one  of  them  and  told  them  to  go  to  the  office  and  get 
thfir  last  pay. 

s  Selecting  Supervisors.  How  to  find  qualified  supervisory  material  is 
indeed  a  critical  problem.  However,  the  key  to  picking  good  supervisors 
is  good  planning.13  It  is  necessary  to  identify  those  employees  who  hold 
promise  of  making  effective  supervisors  before  the  need  for  them  actually 
arises.  This  selection  of  understudies  is  frequently  made  quite  unconsciously. 
The  supervisor  will  turn  to  the  most  dependable  worker  and  ask  him  to 
take  his  place  when  he  is  out  of  the  room  or  to  train  a  new  worker.  Or 
the  supervisor  will  in  some  other  way  indicate  his  preference  among  the 
workers  with  whom  he  has  contact. 

The  trouble  with  this  process  is  that  it  is  frequently  quite  unplanned. 
Furthermore,  it  is  usually  based  on  the  need  of  the  moment.  A  premium 
is  thus  placed  on  dependability;  or  on  the  ability  to  teach — as  in  the  case 
of  training  a  new  worker;  or  even  on  such  a  negative  factor  as  the  super- 
visor's feeling  that  the  man  he  has  selected  is  no  threat  or  competition  to 
him.^The  only  adequate  answer  to  the  problem  of  picking  supervisors  is  to 
have  a  scheme  prepared  well  in  advance.  This  is  a  responsibility  of  top  man- 
agement. Nevertheless,  unless  the  worker  knows  the  plan  that  management 
follows  in  choosing  supervisors  he  cannot  have  much  incentive  and  certainly 
he  will  have  very  little  sense  of  direction  toward  achieving  advancement. 

In  most  work  situations  today,  the  system— if  it  can  be  called  that— for 
picking  supervisors  is  the  very  informal  and  almost  entirely  unplanned 
one  of  observing  the  workers  on  the  job.  When  a  likely  candidate  for  a 
supervisory  post  is  spotted,  his  name  is  recorded  in  the  mind  or  perhaps 
in  the  notebook  of  the  boss,  depending  on  how  systematic  he  is.  When  an 
opportunity  comes  up,  the  various  candidates  the  boss  has  noted  are  inter- 
viewed. Their  work  records  are  compared  and  then  one  man  is  madb 
supervisor. 

This  system,  informal  as  it  may  seem  to  be,  can  be  a  good  one  if  defi- 
nite standards  are  kept  in  mind.  There  may  be  a  personal  history  in  writ- 
ing of  each  worker's  performance,  including  his  performance  under  ten- 
sion, how  he  gets  along  with  his  fellows,  whether  he  is  ambitious,  whether 
he  has  made  any  suggestions  for  improvement  of  the  work,  his  conduct 

18  A  good  introduction  to  supervisory  training  may  be  found  in  Fern,  George  H.,  Training 
for  Supervision  in  Industry,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1945. 


440  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

off  the  job,  and  so  forth.  If  such  a  record  is  not  kept  as  part  of  each  em- 
ployee's personnel  folder,  an  ill-considered  choice  is  much  more  likely. 

The  personal  interview  is  frequently  used,  particularly  if  the  superior 
making  the  selection  of  the  new  supervisor  is  two  or  three  levels  removed 
from  the  candidate  and  does  not  know  his  work  intimately.  The  interview 
is  useful  to  test  personal  traits.  Generally  it  does  not  have  sufficient  validity 
to  contradict  the  record  of  work  experience  or  the  recommendations  of 
former  superiors. 

Recommendation  by  former  superiors  needs  to  be  given  some  weight, 
too,  but  caution  should  be  exercised.  The  supervisor's  recommendation  is 
only  as  good  as  the  supervisor  himself.  If  the  supervisor  is  one  who  for  his 
own  self-protection  will  select  the  worker  who  is  aggressive  and  pushes  him- 
self forward,  or  if  he  notices  only  the  people  who  are  pleasant  and  inoccuous, 
his  recommendation  would  be  misleading  to  that  extent.  By  and  large,  how- 
ever, it  is  to  be  doubted  whether  the  superior,  in  making  a  promotion, 
should  override  the  supervisor's  recommendation. 

Written  tests  are  not  much  in  use  for  the  selection  of  supervisors.  Yet 
such  tests  can  be  helpful  indicators.  A  grave  question  is  whether  inventories 
of  personal  traits  or  basic  interests  may  be  used  with  complete  assurance 
in  a  competitive  situation.  It  has  been  well  established  that  general  intelli- 
gence and  subject-matter  knowledge — how  to  lay  out  a  job,  how  to  issue 
instructions,  how  to  teach — can  be  readily  tested,  not  to  mention  the  funda- 
mentals of  public  administration. 

It  has  also  been  demonstrated  that  the  intelligence  test  alone  is  a  fairly 
good  indicator  to  identify  supervisory  talent,  provided  that  complete  reliance 
is  not  placed  upon  it  but  that  further  screening  takes  place.  The  supervisor 
cannot  be  effective  unless  he  is  superior  in  intelligence,  or  at  a  bare  mini- 
mum as  intelligent  as  the  average  worker  under  him.  Otherwise  he  is  seri- 
ously handicapped  in  his  leadership  and  in  his  acceptance  bf'fhe,  group,  v 

State  and  local  governments  in  certain  jurisdictions  use  the  competitive 
promotional  examination.  This  can  be  a  sound  system,  but  it  depends 
almost  entirely  on  how  it  is  administered.  Mere  posting  of  the  opportunity 
to  take  a  competitive  promotional  examination  would  certainly  not  be 
enough. 

Finally,  there  is  still  another  device— election  of  supervisors  by  their  fel- 
low workers.  This  has  been  tried  in  a  number  of  places  and  found  to  be 
none  too  successful.  Probably  supervisors  should  conduct  themselves  in 
such  a  way  that  they  would  be  the  choice  of  their  workers.  But  it  is  to  be 
doubted  whether  the  most  popular  member  of  a  group  is  always  the  best 
supervisor. 

Even  a  selection  system  combining  most  of  the  elements  here  reviewed 
would  not  guarantee  a  good  supervisor.  He  would  still  have  to  be  tried 
on  the  job;  an  understudy  system  is  therefore  desirable.  Once  workers  with 
supervisory  talent  are  identified,  they  should  be  given  a  chance  of  showing 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  441 

their  ability  as  supervisors.  They  could  act  as  relief  when  their  supervisor  is 
on  sick  leave  or  vacation,  or  during  shorter  periods  when  he  is  called  away 
from  his  post.  During  this  kind  of  probationary  period  when  the  candi- 
date is  acting  as  understudy,  he  should  be  given  training  to  qualify  him 
fully  for  his  job.  His  performance  as  acting  supervisor  and  as  trainee  will 
allow  a  fairly  definitive  rating  of  his  promise. 

Supervision  and  Policy.  The  system  by  which  supervisors  are  picked 
depends  upon  the  policy  of  top  management.  To  what  extent  are  supervis- 
ors the  victims  of  top  policy?  We  are  tempted  to  reply:  In  inverse  propor- 
tion to  the  degree  of  their  use  in  the  determination  of  policy.  In  turn,  their 
participation  in  policy-making  is  in  large  part  a  problem  of  communication 
— getting  information  about  policy  and  underlying  reasons  down  the  hier- 
archy and  policy  suggestions  back  up  again.14  If  the  agency  head  sees  to  it 
that  managers  on  the  intermediate  levels  down  to  the  first-line  supervisors 
meet  regularly  with  their  work  associates  to  discuss  the  objectives  of  the 
organization  and  how  successfully  these  are  being  accomplished,  supervisors 
will  have  an  opportunity  of  contributing  to  the  making  of  policy. 

When  they  do,  they  are  likely  to  press  for  reasonable  flexibility  in  the 
application  of  general  regulations  that  impinge  upon  their  relationship 
with  their  employees.15  There  are  still  too  many  rules  which  require 
supervisors  to  take  specified  action  against  the  employee  irrespective  of  the 
particular  circumstances  of  the  individual  case,  and  sometimes  over  quite 
trivial  matters.  When  the  supervisor's  discretion  is  so  sharply  limited,  he  is 
impaired  in  his  opportunity  for  effective  supervision.  We  are  here  faced 
with  an  inherent  dilemma  of  large-scale  organization.  On  the  one  hand  is 
the  demand  for  uniformity,  and  on  the  other  a  realization  that  for  best 
performance  the  supervisor  requires  as  much  latitude  as  possible. 

It  is  not  in  policy  matters  alone  that  supervisors  may  be  victimized. 
They  are  also  exposed  to  pressures  of  various  sorts  from  higher  levels.  These 
pressures  may  come  from  superiors  in  the  line  of  command  or  from  officers 
in  staff  services  who  may  interfere  in  the  supervisory  situation  for  one  rea- 
son or  another.  Much  of  the  functional  specialization  of  large-scale  organi- 
zation is  in  a  sense  an  interference  with  effective  supervision.  Examples  are 
the  supervisor's  inability  freely  to  reward  exceptional  service  by  increased 
pay,  or  to  hire  and  fire  employees.  In  fact,  certain  state  and  local  jurisdic- 
tions give  the  employees  generally  the  right  to  appeal  to  the  civil  service 
commission  for  reinstatement  on  its  decision. 

One  of  the  sharpest  pressures  which  a  superior  can  bring  on  a  supervisor 
is  pressure  for  greater  production  without  conceding  overtime  compensation. 
Another  example  of  pressure  may  arise  from  employee  counseling  by  special 
staff  services.  During  World  War  II,  especially  in  the  federal  service,  the 

14  For  a  fuller  discussion,  see  above  Ch.  16,  "The  Formulation  of  Administrative  Policy." 

15  For  further  discussion,  sec  above  Ch.  17,  "Government  by  Procedure,"  especially  sec.  4, 
"Creation  and  Criteria." 


442  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

supervisor's  job  of  looking  after  the  morale  of  his  employees  was  almost 
completely  taken  over  in  some  agencies  by  an  employee-relations  staff,  par- 
ticularly by  the  employee  counselor.  The  more  technical  specialists  there 
are  in  personnel  and  management-planning  offices,  the  greater  is  the  tempta- 
tion to  exert  various  pressures  on  the  supervisor— indeed,  to  make  him  abdi- 
cate certain  of  his  responsibilities  and  pass  them  over  to  these  technicians. 
Specialization— notwithstanding  its  general  merits— thus  causes  another 
dilemma  in  first-line  supervision. 

Span  of  Supervision.  A  specific  problem  which  deserves  consideration 
might  be  called  that  of  the  span  of  supervision.  How  many  workers  can 
one  supervisor  control  effectively?  This  is  not  the  way  the  number  of  work- 
ers assigned  to  the  supervisor  is  usually  determined,  however.  The  super- 
visor is  simply  given  a  block  of  work  to  do  and  the  number  of  workers 
deemed  adequate  to  handle  it,  without  much  thought  of  the  problem  of 
span  of  supervision.  Under  the  pressure  of  what  may  be  an  impossible 
assignment,  the  supervisor  can  very  well  break  down  or  resign  himself  to 
doing  an  inadequate  job. 

It  is  not  possible  to  give  a  definite  answer  to  the  question  of  "the  span  of 
supervision."  Graicunas16  tried  it  by  insisting  that  no  superior  should  super- 
vise more  than  three  subordinates,  but  immediately  we  would  have  to  make 
an  exception  at  the  first  level  of  supervision  because  so  many  employees 
carry  on  rather  mechanical  tasks  which  require  a  minimum  of  surveillance. 
In  other  words,  the  span  of  supervision  depends  upon  the  homogeneity  of 
the  work,  its  mechanical  or  nonmechanical  nature,  the  proficiency  of 
the  workers,  and  so  on.  In  short,  it  depends  upon  the  amount  of  attention 
the  supervisor  needs  to  give  to  each  individual  worker.  Naturally,  the  more 
time  he  has  to  spend  with  each,  the  fewer  he  can  supervise. 

It  is  doubtful,  however,  whether  a  single  supervisor  can  supervise  more 
than  six  or  seven  workers  unless  their  tasks  are  almost  entirely  mechanized 
and  routinized.  True,  the  supervisor  can  save  himself  a  lot  of  time  by 
organizing  his  own  job.  There  are  many  internal  controls  such  as  produc- 
tion records  and  quality  control  records  which  can  save  the  supervisor 
many  steps  and  much  personal  attention,  thereby  lengthening  his  span 
of  supervision. 

Employee  Organization  and  Supervision.  Something  has  been  said  in 
the  preceding  discussion  about  the  new  democratic  approach  to  supervision. 
Reference  has  been  made  to  the  employee  union.  This  changed  situation 
constitutes  a  novel  problem  for  supervision.  In  the  first  place,  in  a  highly 
unionized  plant  or  office— and  most  governmental  jurisdictions,  especially 
the  larger  ones,  are  now  unionized  at  least  in  part— democracy  has  been 

16  "Relationship  in  Organization,"  in  Gulick,  Luther  and  Urwick,  L.,  eds,,  Papers  on  the 
Science  of  Administration,  p.  183  ff.t  New  York:  Institute  of  Public  Administration,  1937. 
C/.  also  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  of  Organization,"  sec.  3,  "Quest  of  Organizational 
Unity." 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  443 

forced  upon  the  supervisor  by  the  very  organization  of  the  employees.  He 
has  to  deal  with  grievances  consistently  because  he  is  confronted  by  an 
organized  group.  He  has  to  discuss  hours  of  work,  assignment  of  work,  or 
whatever  the  topic  of  a  complaint  may  be,  in  terms  of  the  weight  of 
numbers. 

Nor  is  that  all.  As  factories  have  their  shop  stewards  who  speak  for  the 
union  even  though  they  are  also  employees  themselves,  so  the  government- 
employee  unions  have  their  spokesmen.  What  happens  to  the  undivided 
authority  of  the  supervisor  when  he  is  dealing  with  a  shop  steward  about 
one  of  the  supervisor's  workers?  Certainly  the  pure  concept  of  hierarchy 
is  affected.  The  employee  union  by  its  very  existence  puts  a  premium  upon 
intelligence  on  the  part  of  the  supervisor,  upon  a  progressive  philosophy  in 
his  dealings  with  workers,  and  upon  his  skill  in  negotiations  not  only  face 
to  face  with  his  employees  but  also  with  others  outside  his  shop.  The  prob- 
lem of  the  employee  union  might  well  be  pondered  by  those  who  are 
selecting  prospective  supervisors. 

Another  entirely  different  question  comes  up  in  connection  with  unioni- 
zation— the  question  of  whether  the  supervisor  himself  is  to  be  unionized.17 
There  is  still  considerable  public  controversy  about  the  issue  whether 
foremen  in  factories  and  supervisors  in  offices  may  belong  to  labor  unions 
or  whether  they  are— as  management  contends — an  integral  part  of  the 
executive  system.  The  truth  is,  of  course,  that  the  supervisor  in  this  matter 
is  on  the  fence,  or  in  an  organizational  no  man's  land.  Being  raised  from 
among  the  workers,  being  in  daily  contact  with  them,  the  first-line  super- 
visor, if  he  has  any  sympathy  at  all,  very  readily  identifies  himself  with 
them. 

On  the  other  hand,  no  one  can  deny  that  even  supervisors  in  the  first 
line  are  the  fingers  of  the  hands  of  management.  They  are  not  only  first- 
line  supervisors  but  first-line  executives  as  well.  We  could  conjecture  that 
the  supervisor  would  regard  himself  as  a  manager  and  an  executive  only 
when  his  place  as  such  is  clearly  indicated  to  him  by  top  management 
and  only  when  management  is  sympathetic  to  the  individual  worker.  If 
the  worker  is  in  fact  suppressed  or  exploited  by  management,  the  sympa- 
thetic supervisor  will  be  prone  to  side  with  the  workers  in  a  controversy 
between  them  and  management. 

Short-Run  Versus  Long-Run  Point  of  View.  Many  of  the  problems  of 
supervision  can  be  telescoped  into  one  question — that  of  the  short-run  versus 
the  long-run  point  of  view.  A  management  which  insists  on  immediate 
top  production  at  any  given  level  of  work  proficiency  without  taking  time 
and  money  for  training  in  order  to  up-grade  the  worker  or  give  him  an 
opportunity  to  train  and  develop  himself,  pursues  a  policy  which  has  far- 

17  An  excellent  discussion  of  the  industrial  aspect  of  the  matter  is  contained  in  Roethlis- 
berger,  Fritz  J.,  "The  Foreman:  Master  and  Victim  of  Double  Talk,"  Harvard  Business  Review, 
1945,  Vol.  23,  p.  283  ff. 


444  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 

reaching  implications  for  the  supervisor's  role.  This  kind  of  attitude  on  the 
part  of  top  management  causes  a  situation  in  which  the  job  contends  against 
the  individual's  personal  development. 

In  the  past,  government  has  generally  refused  to  facilitate  training 
and  educational  opportunity  by  placing  immediate  efficiency  ahead  of  long- 
run  self-development.  The  supervisor  who  tries  to  "hang  on  to  his  good 
men"  rather  than  let  them  go  out  and  get  additional  experience  elsewhere 
is  doing  the  same  kind  of  blocking.  When  supervisors  are  job-conscious 
rather  than  people-conscious,  they  are  going  to  make  such  mistakes.  How 
long  will  it  take  the  employee  unions  to  wake  up  to  these  considerations? 

To  be  sure,  the  emphasis  in  position  classification  must  be  on  the  job 
rather  than  on  the  individual  if  the  classification  system  is  to  be  objective. 
Nevertheless,  any  one  who  has  had  experience  in  working  with  groups 
of  people  knows  that  the  only  workable  long-run  arrangement  is  to  give 
every  individual  an  opportunity  to  find  the  type  of  work  for  which  he  has 
greatest  aptitude,  and  then  to  help  him  actively  to  develop  himself  to 
capacity.  In  broadest  terms,  this  is  a  question  as  to  how  much  of  each 
day  is  going  to  be  given  to  planning  for  future  days,  and  how  much  of 
the  daily  production  may  be  sacrificed  in  order  to  gain  some  time  for 
training  to  increase  efficiency  and  productivity  for  the  future.  The  balance 
may  vary  with  different  situations,  but  there  certainly  must  be  a  balance. 

Do  we  make  the  most  of  supervision?  The  answer  is:  We  do  not  by 
any  means.  Government  particularly  has  sinned  in  this  respect.  Govern- 
ment, by  developing  civil  service  systems  and  higher  staff  services  such  as 
personnel,  budgeting,  and  management  planning,  in  a  sense  has  tried  to 
make  up  for  deficiencies  in  supervision.  It  took  another  world  war  and 
the  pressing  need  for  increased  work  with  decreased  manpower  to  drive 
us  into  a  sounder  consideration  of  supervision.  At  the  same  time,  the  devel- 
opment of  labor  unions  and  the  extension  of  the  idea  of  democracy  from 
the  political  arena  into  the  economic  and  the  workaday  world  have  under- 
scored the  importance  of  supervision.  To  put  it  paradoxically,  we  have 
moved  away  from  hierarchical  considerations  because  of  better-organized 
worker  interests,  only  to  be  led  back  to  hierarchical  considerations  demo- 
cratically conceived. 

4.  SUPERVISION  AND  EMPLOYEE  INITIATIVE 

Institutional  Climate.  The  character  of  supervision  in  any  given  organi- 
zation is  neither  merely  a  reflection  of  a  particular  function  or  activity  that 
is  being  supervised  nor  principally  the  result  of  the  personal  qualifications 
of  the  supervisor,  important  as  these  are.  We  must  take  into  account  still 
another  factor— the  "institutional  climate";  that  is,  the  policies  which  are 
imposed  upon  the  supervisor  by  top  management  and  the  attitudes  of  execu- 
tives and  managers  on  the  intermediate  levels  above  the  first-line  supervisor. 

For  example,  nonrecognition  of  unions  will  have  a  great  deal  to  do  with 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  445 

the  character  of  supervision  in  any  institution.  Usually  the  good  supervisor 
is  able  to  make  the  employee  loyal  to  the  organization,  but  the  development 
of  such  loyalty  becomes  an  impossible  task  when  the  climate  of  the  insti- 
tution is  frigid  and  repulsive  to  the  worker.  The  good  supervisor  is  worker- 
centered,  but  how  can  he  be  worker-centered  if  no  one  above  him  is 
interested  in  the  worker? 

Top  Management  Support.  It  is  therefore  highly  important  that  top 
management  identify  itself  with  the  supervisor.  One  way  of  doing  this  is 
to  make  sure  that  the  supervisor  is  properly  selected,  trained,  and  paid. 

Second,  he  should  be  kept  constantly  informed,  not  only  of  company 
policy  which  affects  production,  but  also  of  policy  in  every  other  respect, 
so  that  he  will  be  in  effect  a  part  of  the  stream  of  consciousness  of  the  or- 
ganization as  a  whole.  This  applies  with  special  emphasis  to  government 
agencies.  If  the  head  of  the  agency  is  satisfied  to  make  policy  and  pass 
it  down  as  a  court  hands  out  its  decisions,  he  need  not  be  surprised  if  the 
supervisors  fail  to  identify  themselves  with  him.  If,  however,  the  super- 
visors are  constantly  consulted  and  kept  informed,  if  there  are  frequent 
staff  conferences  at  each  level  of  the  organization,  there  will  be  in  effect 
only  one  identity  to  the  organization.  We  might  say  that  any  top  manage- 
ment which  loses  its  foremen  or  supervisors  to  a  union  deserves  to  suffer 
this  loss. 

Channeling  Employee  Initiative.  In  brief,  top  management  may  encour- 
age or  stifle  the  supervisor.  He  may  be  made  a  mindless  cog  of  control. 
Yet  it  is  obvious  that  he  .should  never  try  to  substitute  for  the  initiative 
of  Uie"employee.  The  real  job  of  supervision  is  how  to  furnish  control  and 
guidance  without  destroying  employee  initiative.  In  terms  of  production 
the  very  purpose  of  hierarchy  is  to  free  the  workers  of  organizational  im- 
pediments so  that  they  can  spend  their  full  time  and  full  energy  on  the 
task  of  getting  the  work  done. 

The  supervisor  who  has  sympathy  for  the  worker,  who  is  interested  in 
the  worker's  problems,  who  lets  the  worker  talk  and  even  "talk  back,"  who 
fights  the  worker's  battles  with  the  higher  manager,  will  not  be  inclined 
to  stifle  the  initiative  of  his  employees.  This  is  not  chough,  however.  It 
is  necessary  in  addition  that  workers  have  a  market  for  their  initiative,"!?© 
to^  speak.  "This  may  be  furnished  by  an  employee-suggestion  system~~ 
~  Suggestion  Systems.  The  suggestion  box,  periodic  awards,  and  plant 
publicity  can  hope  to  achieve  only  partial  results  at  best.  Moreover,  if  the 
workers  are  convinced  that  the  scheme  is  primarily  for  the  benefit  of  the 
stockholder,  the  employee-suggestion  system  is  not  going  to  work  anyway. 
However,  many  suggestion  systems  have  been  effective,  and  the  methods 
required  for  their  operation  are  well  established.  J.  M.  Juran,  in  his  Bureau- 
cracy—A Challenge  to  Better  Management,1*  lists  eight  essential  require- 

i*  New  York:  Harper,  1944,  p.  117  (by  permission  of  the  publisher). 


446  THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION 


ments  for  jjjggffTfrfiil  «*mplnyge-aiiggefit  inn 
preferTto  call  it,  "employee-participation"  system: 

(1)  Announced  official  support  of  such  a  plan;  (2)  a  channel  for  sug- 
gestions separate  from  normal  supervision;  (3)  prompt  acknowledge- 
ment of  the  receipt  of  suggestions;  (4)  fair  and  impartial  investigation 
of  each  suggestion;  (5)  progress  reports  to  the  employee  where  the  in- 
vestigation takes  a  long  time;  (6)  final  report  issued  with  prior 
knowledge,  if  not  concurrence,  of  the  employee;  (7)  a  recording  in  the 
employee's  personnel  record  of  (a)  his  making  the  suggestion  and  (b) 
results  obtained;  and  (8)  a  system  of  reward  for  valuable  suggestions. 

Juran  goes  on  to  point  out  that  the  system  can  be  varied.  It  may  be 
merely  a  record  of  suggestions  for  the  recognition  of  the  worker's  merit. 
It  may  operate  on  nonfinancial  recognition  —  for  example,  a  letter  from  top 
management.  It  may  establish  promotion  preference.  And  it  may  involve 
tangible  rewards  in  the  form  of  a  gold  medal,  a  bronze  plaque,  or  a  grant 
of  money.  During  World  War  II,  several  federal  departments  established 
such  suggestion  systems  with  considerable  benefit  to  their  operations.10 
LThe  suggestion  system  is  not  the  orily  form  of  stimulating  employee  initia- 
tive. Under  the  so-called-ABC  conference,  various  groups  throughout  the 
hierarchy  down  To^tKe^lowest  levSclticet  together  to  give  each  individual 
an  opportunity  to  speaK  BTslnmcOfln  the  absence  of  such  an  arrangement, 
regular  supervisor  conferences  have  proved  to  be  valuable  on  all  levels, 
including  that  of  first-line  supervision.  Employee  clubs  with  ostensibly 
recreational  purposes  may  also  be  effective  morale-builders  and  vehicles  for 
free  discussion  of  work  problems  as  well.  Like  the  best  kind  of  army 
officer,  the  supervisor  in  government  must  be  ever  alert  in  his  concern  for 
his  men.  I£  he  shows  the  same  concern  for  strengthening  and  equipping 
his  workers  that  the  company  commander  does  for  feeding,  clothing,  and 
sheltering  his  company,  he  would  come  close  to  the  practical  ideal  of 
supervision. 

Rating  Employees.  A  good  employee-rating  system  requires  definite 
standards  of  performance  and  thus  assists  in  work  programming  and  work 
scheduling.20  It  also  leads  naturally  to  the  improvement  of  performance  — 
that  is,  training.  In  discussing  with  the  employee  the  rating  given  and 
the  reasons  for  it,  the  supervisor  has  a  precious  opportunity  of  winning 
:onfidence,  correcting  weaknesses,  and  prompting  new  zest  by  objective 
praise.  The  supervisor  can  succeed  only  in  terms  of  his  personal  relations 
with  the  worker  in  giving  a  complete  judgment  of  the  latter's  performance. 
Without  such  close  contact  and  conditions  of  candor,  the  supervisor's 
reports  to  his  superiors  are  worthless. 

10  Cf.  Donaho,  John  A.,  "Employee  Suggestion  Systems  in  the  Public  Service,"  Public 
Personnel  Review,  1945,  Vol.  6,  p.  230  ff.  See  also  below  Ch.  20,  "Administrative  Self  -Im- 
provement," sec.  4,  "Basic  Resources  in  Management  Improvement." 

20  Cf.  above  Ch.  18,  "The  Tasks  of  Middle  Management,"  sec.  3,  "Running  the  Show." 


THE  ART  OF  SUPERVISION  447 

The  quest  in  public  administration  has  been  primarily  for  a  foolproof 
form  of  performance  rating.  The  number  of  revisions  of  rating  forms 
in  the  federal  government  testifies  to  this  search  for  a  magic  tool.  However, 
many  governmental  jurisdictions  have  abandoned  the  search  and  have  spent 
their  time  more  profitably  on  improving  the  ability  of  the  wielders  of  the 
tool — the  supervisors  themselves.  The  supervisor  must  be  able  to  sit  down 
with  the  worker  and  go  over  his  whole  performance,  winding  up  by  recom- 
mending to  him  concretely  what  he  can  do  to  improve  his  work.  Fear  of 
such  a  session  is  perhaps  the  key  to  excessively  formal  supervision  and 
neglect  of  real  supervisory  responsibility,  especially  in  governmental  jurisdic- 
tions where  performance  rating  has  been  highly  formalized. 


CHAPTER 


Administrative  Self-Improvement 

1.   EVOLUTIONARY  CURRENTS 

Beginnings  of  the  Analytical  Approach.  As  we  have  seen  earlier,1  the 
analytical  approach  to  American  public  administration  is  o£  relatively  recent 
origin.  We  may  trace  it  back  to  the  establishment  of  the  New  York  Bureau 
of  Municipal  Research  in  1906.  The  methodically  planned  and  systemati- 
cally executed  surveys  undertaken  by  that  bureau  led  to  many  striking 
improvements  in  Uie  government  of  the  city.  The  success  of  those  surveys 
won  almost  instantaneous  recognition  for  the  analytical  approach  that  sup- 
ported them.  Unscrupulous  politicians  could  not  withstand  the  force  of 
facts  thus  brought  to  light.  Indeed,  it  was  this  widening  exposition  of  the 
darker  aspects  of  city  government  which  ushered  in  the  reform  administra- 
tion of  John  Purroy  Mitchel  from  1914  to  1918. 

Other  communities,  noting  these  achievements,  called  on  the  New  York 
Bureau  for  help.  Surveys  were  made  of  cities,  counties,  and  states  through- 
out the  country,  and  even  abroad.  Citizens  in  these  jurisdictions  saw  that 
facts  were  more  powerful  than  partisan  assertions.  As  a  result,  bureaus 
of  governmental  research  sprang  up  in  many  communities,  often  staffed  by 
those  trained  at  the  New  York  Bureau. 

These  governmental  research  agencies  carried  forward  the  basic  reforms 
initiated  in  the  late  nineteenth  century — elimination  of  the  spoils  system; 
municipal  home  rule;  election  reform;  and  direct  popular  control  through 
referendum  and  recall  of  officials.  New  programs  were  added,  such  as  the 
short  ballot;  strengthening  the  chief  executive;  elimination  of  administration 
by  legislative  committees  and  boards;  establishment  of  budget,  accounting, 
and  audit  systems;  departmental  reorganization;  scientific  tax  assessment; 
centralized  purchasing;  and  judicial  reform.  The  National  Municipal 
League,  established  in  1894,  gained  in  influence  as  it  incorporated  many  of 
these  features  in  its  model  city  charter  and  provided  a  clearing  house  of  best 
practices  for  citizen  groups. 

1  Sec  above  Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration." 

448 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  449 

Growth  of  Systematic  Inquiry.  The  Commission  on  Economy  and 
Efficiency,  appointed  in  1910  by  President  Taft,  was  in  large  part  an  out- 
growth of  the  work  of  the  governmental  research  bureaus.  The  commit- 
tee presented  a  series  of  reports  on  the  necessity  for  a  national  budget  sys- 
tem, better  departmental  working  methods,  and  other  administrative  re- 
forms in  the  federal  government.  While  no  immediate  action  was  taken 
by  Congress,  the  studies  paved  the  way  for  later  improvement,  and  the 
ideas  they  set  forth  lived  on.  Similar  work  was  put  under  way  in  New 
York  State  under  Governor  Charles  E.  Hughes.  Ultimately,  a  thorough- 
going reorganization  of  the  state  government  grew  out  of  the  proposals  of 
the  New  York  Constitutional  Convention  of  1915. 

Special  commissions  of  inquiry  appointed  by  state  and  local  chief  execu- 
tives appeared  with  increasing  frequency  as  the  years  went  by.  Likewise, 
legislative  committees  undertook  inquiries  of  their  own.  One  of  the  most 
noteworthy  of  these  was  the  Special  Joint  Committee  on  Taxation  and 
Retrenchment  in  New  York  State,  which  began  its  work  in  1921  under  the 
chairmanship  of  Frederick  Davenport.  Its  reports  provided  excellent  source 
material  for  the  student  and  practitioner  of  public  administration  every- 
where, as  well  as  many  tangible  benefits  to  New  York  state  and  local 
government. 

In  more  recent  years,  both  congressional  committees  and  presidents  have 
given  increasing  attention  to  organizational  and  administrative  problems.2 
In  1937,  comprehensive  reports  on  these  subjects  were  submitted  by  the 
President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management3  and  by  the  Brook- 
ings  Institution,4  the  latter  employed  by  the  Select  Committee  to  Investigate 
the  Executive  Agencies  of  the  Government,  known  as  the  Byrd  Committee. 
The  Brookings  study  was  the  last  intensive  effort  in  the  field  of  federal 
departmental  organization  made  by  Congress,  although  during  World  War 
II  the  so-called  Truman  and  Ramspeck  committees  made  noteworthy 
investigations  of  specific  aspects  of  administration.  While  these  inquiries 
resulted  in  the  tightening  of  operations  and  the  elimination  of  instances  of 
inefficiency,  few  tangible  gains  in  administrative  organization  have  emerged 
from  direct  congressional  action.  On  the  other  hand,  the  work  of  the  Presi- 
dent's Committee  on  Administrative  Management  has  been  outstanding. 
Its  report  prepared  the  way  for  important  organizational  improvements  that 
were  effected  on  the  eve  of  World  War  II. 

Academic  and  Professional  Support.  Suchjefforts  from  an  early  date 
required  men  and  women  trained  in  governmental  research  and  analysis. 
The  staff  of  the  New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research  had  been  in  great 
demand  in  many  places.  To  meet  this  demand,  the  bureau  in  1911  set  up 

2  For  a  historical  survey,  see  Meriam,  Lewis  and  Schmeckebier,  Laurence  P.,  Reorgani- 
zation of  the  National  Government,  p.  181  #.,  Washington:  Brookings  Institution,  1939. 
8  See  its  Report  with  Special  Studies,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office.  1937. 
4  Senate  Report  No.  1275,  75th  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1937. 


450  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

a  Training  School  for  Public  Service.  The  program  acquired  characteristic 
features  of  graduate  training  under  Charles  A.  Beard  in  1915  and  later 
under  William  E.  Mosher.  About  the  same  time,  the  universities  began  to 
be  interested  not  only  in  governmental  research  but  also  in  training  students 
for  research  and  administrative  posts.  Many  universities — such  as  Syracuse, 
Columbia,  Chicago,  Minnesota,  Harvard,  and  Alabama,  to  name  only  a 
few — have  formulated  specific  curricula  for  this  purpose.5 

Foundations  likewise  became  interested  in  better  government  manage- 
ment. They  granted  funds  to  universities  for  research  and  training  pro- 
grams. They  also  gave  support  to  the  work  of  the  New  York  Bureau  of 
Municipal  Research — since  1932  the  Institute  of  Public  Administration — and 
to  basic  studies  like  those  carried  on  by  President  Hoover's  Committee  on 
Social  Trends,  the  Commission  of  Inquiry  on  Public  Service  Personnel 
(1934-1935),  and  the  Committee  on  Public  Administration  of  the  Social 
Science  Research  Council.6 

Reflecting  an  increasingly  professional  attitude  toward  public  adminis- 
tration, public  officials  have  grouped  together  in  organizations  for  the  ex- 
change of  experience'  and  information.  Even  before  1900,  a  number  of 
such  bodies  were  making  contributions  to  better  government — for  example, 
the  American  Public  Health  Association,  the  International  Association  of 
Chiefs  of  Police,  and  the  American  Society  for  Municipal  Improvements. 
A  related  early  development  was  the  establishment  of  state  leagues  of  mu- 
nicipalities, which  devoted  their  attention  to  arousing  interest  in  improv- 
ing municipal  practices  and  in  presenting  the  needs  of  the  cities  to  state 
legislatures. 

The  work  of  such  associations  was  given  great  impetus  in  the  early 
1930's  by  the  foundation  of  the  Public  Administration  Clearing  House  in 
Chicago.  It  became  the  headquarters  of  a  dozen  or  more  organizations  of 
public  authorities  and  officials  under  one  roof,  commonly  known  as  the 
"1313  Group"  (1313  East  60th  Street).  Its  members— typified  by  the  Council 
of  State  Governments,  the  American  Municipal  Association,  the  Interna- 
tional City  Managers  Association,  the  Municipal  Finance  Officers  Associa- 
tion, the  Civil  Service  Assembly,  the  American  Public  Welfare  Association, 
and  the  American  Public  Works  Association — are  today  enlisting  thousands 
of  officials  in  the  cause  of  sound  administration  through  conferences,  profes- 
sional journals,  and  dissemination  of  research.  Consulting,  research,  and 
publication  services  are  rendered  through  a  joint  agency,  the  Public 
Administration  Service. 

Stimulus  from  Private  Management.  Even  before  the  search  fo/  new 
administrative  methods  was  under  way  in  government,  jnoneers  in  industry 

*Cf.  Graham,  George  A.,  Education  for  Public  Administration,  Chicago:  Public  Admin- 
istration Service,  1941. 

*Cf.  Anderson,  William  and  Gaus,  John  M.,  Research  in  Public  Administration,  Chicago: 
Public  Administration  Service.  1945. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  451 

^ad^dcvcloped  a  fruitful  technique  of  studying  production  proDiems,  even- 
t^aTly  fn  he  knq^m  as  ''scientihcnmanagcmenr^  Faced  with  the  evTdcntTacr 
that  employers  were  unable  to  adjust  themselves  to  the  great  industrial  ex- 
pansion after  the  Civil  War,  these  pioneers  began  to  study  the  methods  by 
which  production  was  controlled. 

Historically,  the  movement  began  in  1886  when  Henry  R.  Towne  read 
his  paper  entitled  "The  Engineer  as  Economist,"  before  the  American  So- 
ciety of  Mechanical  Engineers.  Towne  proposed  that  an  engineer  should 
not  only  be  interested  in  the  invention,  design,  and  installation  of  a  machine, 
but  also  in  devising  means  for  the  most  effective  operation  in  the  shop. 
This  idea  of  bringing  the  engineer  into  the  problems  of  production  sug- 
gested an  entirely  new  relationship  between  employers  and  specialists.  Its 
full  implications  were  not  explored  by  the  society  that  Towne  had  addressed, 
which  confined  itself  to  discussing  devices  and  methods  of  improvement  in 
industry  suggested  by  the  experience  of  its  members.  It  did  not  attempt  to 
develop  a  body  of  principles,  but  dealt  with  particular  problems  that  were  of 
general  interest,  such  as  piece  rates. 

Meanwhile,  Frederick  W.  Taylor — as  worker  and  later  as  foreman — 
was  observing  the  causes  of  waste,  breakdown  in  production,  inefficiency  in 
the  use  of  materials  and  machines,  conflict  between  workers  and  employers, 
and  almost  total  lack  of  planning.  Taylor  began  his  inquiries  by  examin- 
ing the  daily  problems  of  the  shop.  He  experimented  with  all  the  variables 
connected  with  a  certain  operation,  machine,  or  material  until  he  found 
the  best  method  of  doing  the  job.  He  studied,  measured,  and  then  set  up 
specifications. 

When  the  best  method  was  found,  Taylor  needed  to  transmit  it  to  the 
other  foremen.  Thus  training  became  an  additional  aspect  of  his  approach. 
He  discovered  that  the  study  of  one  phase  of  operations  led  to  another*— 
to  the  relations  of  labor  and  management,  and  finally  to  the  problems  of 
over-all  organization.  Taylor's  ideas  were  presented  in  his  Principles  of 
Scientific  Management,  published  in  191 1.7  The  volume  awakened  world- 
wide interest  in  management  circles.  It  was  translated  into  more  than  a 
dozen  languages  and  exerted  a  strong  influence  in  France,  Germany,  Eng^ 
land,  and  Japan.8 

*"*  FurthentttRtrktion  for  the  study  of  production  costs  resulted  from 
hearings  before  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  in  1910-1911.  In  these 
hearings  the  shipper  interests,  which  were  opposing  a  railroad's  request 
for  a  rate  increase,  demanded  that  the  railroad  make  every  effort  to  de- 
crease its  operating  costs  before  being  granted  an  increase.  As  evidence  of 
the  great  savings  that  could  be  made  by  careful  operating  methods,  the  ship- 
per interests  cited  the  economies  derived  from  Taylor's  work  in  several 

7  RepubHshcd  New  York:  Harper,  1934. 

8  See  Person,  Harlow  S.,  "The  Genius  of  Frederick  W.  Taylor,"  Advanced  Management, 
1945,  Vol.  10,  p.  2  ff. 


452  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

industrial  plants.  Some  of  Taylor's  associates,  among  them  Henry  L.  Gantt 
and  Frank  B.  Gilbreth,  were  called  to  testify  on  the  new  approach  to  man- 
agement. It  was  at  this  time  that  the  term  "scientific  management"  was 
coined  and  first  used  publicly.  The  publicity  growing  out  of  these  hearings 
contributed  to  wider  acceptance  of  the  movement  by  industry.9 

After  World  War  I,  the  formation  of  management  societies  helped  to 
raise  professional  standards  and  to  disseminate  information  on  new  tech- 
niques to  a  much  broader  audience.  Among  these  bodies  were  two  organiza- 
tions which  later  joined  forces  to  form  the  Society  for  the  Advancement  of 
Management.  In  1919,  the  National  Office  Management  Association  began 
to  apply  to  office  routine  the  methods  used  in  shops. 

Government  Response.  Government  has  increasingly  utilized  the  meth-j 
ods  of  scientific  management.  Perhaps  the  relatively  slow  start  was  dui 
to  the  inapplicability  of  many  of  the  early  techniques  to  governmental 
functions.  In  recent  years,  as  scientific  management  has  concerned  itseli! 
more  with  problems  of  planning,  organization,  personnel,  and  administra-j 
tion,  it  has  had  more  to  offer  to  governmental  staffs.  A  common  element} 
in  these  two  noteworthy  movements  toward  administrative  progress — thd 
one  in  industry  and  the  other  in  government — has  been  the  spirit  of  objecl 
tive  inquiry  and  analysis.  While  techniques  have  changed,  the  geneM* 
approach  has  remained  the  same. 

2.  ORGANIZATION  FOR  ADMINISTRATIVE  ANALYSIS 

Conceivable  Alternatives.  The  chief  executive  of  a  government  or  the 
head  of  a  department,  bureau,  or  division  may  approach  the  task  of  ad- 
ministrative self-improvement  from  a  number  of  angles.  Whatever  the 
angle,  the  task  breaks  down  essentially  into  constant  review  and  effort  to 
obtain  better  operations  in  terms  of  what  is  done,  who  does  it,  and  how  it 
is  done. 

Obviously,  the  governmental  executive  cannot  concern  himself  with  the 
details  of  administrative  analysis.  He  may,  by  personal  action,  resolve 
some  problem  or  difficulty.  Exercising  general  supervision  is  itself  in  large 
measure  a  job  of  adjusting  and  resolving  organizational  and  procedural 
matters,  and  of  training  subordinates  to  fit  into  the  operation.  The  govern- 
mental executive  can,  however,  do  only  a  small  part  of  the  job  personally 
and  will  need  to  supply  himself  with  various  types  of  aids. 

He  could  employ  outside  consultants  to  work  out  proposals  for  improve- 
ment and  to  assist  in  their  installation.  Or  committees  of  key  line-subor- 
dinates or  staff  officials  within  the  organization  may  be  appointed  as 
particular  problems  arise.  Periodic  meetings  may  provide  a  setting  for 
throwing  administrative  problems  on  the  table  for  discussion  and  resolu- 

9  See  also  House  of  Representatives,  Committee  on  Labor,  Hearings  on  the  Taylor  system, 
62d  Cong.,  1st  Sess.,  1911. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  453 

tion.  An  administrative  "general  staff"— budgeting,  personnel,  admin- 
istrative-planning,  and  programming  officers — provides  another  instrument 
for  analyzing  and  disposing  of  major  questions  of  organization  and 
management. 

In  accomplishing  the  task  of  raising  the  general  level  of  management, 
the  administrator  must  bring  his  line  operators  and  supervisors  into  the 
total  effort  for  improvement.,/  On  them  rests  principal  responsibility  for 
initiating  or  carrying  but  most  of  the  modifications  which  will  be  made 
from  day  to  day  or  week  to  week.  In  the  process  of  harnessing  the  ener- 
gies of  his  operators  and  supervisors,  the  administrator  must  also  bring  about 
participation  and  support  on  the  part  of  the  rank  and  file  of  employees. 

All  of  these  are  not  alternatives  limiting  the  choice  of  the  administrator. 
Each  supplements  the  other.  Each  warrants  consideration  in  the  total  picture. 
Each  plays  a  part  in  the  broader  context. 

Improvement  Through  the  Administrator's  Personal  Action.  The  skilled 
administrator  in  the  course  of  a  day's  work  has  many  opportunities  to 
bring  about  informally  adjustments  which  will  remedy  existing  difficulties 
or  prevent  future  trouble  and  friction.  How  effective  he  is  at  this  depends 
upon  the  keenness  of  his  observation  of  the  organization  at  work  and  his 
sensitivity  to  the  existence  of  bottlenecks,  conflicts  in  responsibility,  personal 
maladjustments,  and  outmoded  methods. 

Unobstructed  flow  of  information  to  him  from  his  staff  officers  and  from 
operating  officials  will  help.  Complaints  coming  from  them  will  often 
lead  to  the  detection  of  fire  under  the  smoke.  If  the  fire  is  not  big,  the 
administrator  can  put  it  out  himself.  Usually  he  is  unable  to  do  it  alone. 
Rather  he  must  rely  upon  his  subordinates.  If  this  is  to  work  out,  he 
must  provide  a  fertile  environment  which  will  stimulate  administrative 
improvement  by  those  subordinates.  Generally,  the  administrator's  principal 
contribution  will  be  the  giving  of  considered  assent  to  changes  which  have 
come  up  to  him  for  approval  from  his  general  staff,  from  his  operators, 
from  consultants,  or  from  meetings  of  groups  within  and  without  the  or- 
ganization concerned  with  specific  problems.10 

Use  of  Outside  Consultants.  Government  agencies  often  are  confronted 
with  administrative  problems  which  require  intensive  study  beyond  what 
can  be  done  by  the  regular  staff.  Or,  for  example,  the  balance  of  personal 
factors  may  be  such  that  no  one  within  the  agency  can  deal  with  such 
major  problems  effectively.  In  these  situations,  an  outside  viewpoint  or  the 
utilization  of  experts  who  have  been  schooled  in  solving  similar  problems 
in  many  jurisdictions  will  be  essential. 

To  meet  such  special  needs,  outside  consultants  have  been  employed  by 

10  For  a  fuller  discussion,  see  Stone,  Donald  C.,  "Notes  on  the  Governmental  Executive: 
His  Role  and  His  Methods,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  210  ff.  This 
paper  is  also  available  in  "New  Horizons  in  Public  Administration,  University,  Ala.:  University 
of  Alabama  Press,  1945. 


454  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

government,  federal,  state,  and  local,  with  increasing  frequency  in  recent 
years.  Well  known  are  the  surveys  made  by  the  Institute  of  Public  Ad- 
ministration, the  Public  Administration  Service,  the  Brookings  Institution, 
ind  private  consulting  firms  to  develop  broad  plans  for  governmental  re- 
organization. Their  efforts  have  been  concerned  ordinarily  with  the  fun- 
damental aspects  of  better  structure  and  management,  and  not  with  the 
minutiae  of  administration. 

Less  far-reaching  in  scope,  but  more  important  for  the  development  of 
jound  administrative  practices,  is  the  extent  to  which  federal,  state,  and 
local  administrators  arrange  with  consultants  to  work  as  temporary  rein- 
forcements of  their  staffs,  without  publicity  or  fanfare.  For  example,  the 
War  Production  Board  brought  in  the  director  of  the  Institute  of  Public 
Administration  to  serve  temporarily  as  head  of  its  Organizational  Planning 
Division.  The  Petroleum  Administration  for  War  employed  the  director 
of  the  management  department  of  Standard  Oil  of  California  as  adviser  on 
administrative  problems.  Some  of  the  staff  members  of  the  Navy  Depart- 
ment's Office  of  the  Management  Engineer  were  recruited  from  industrial 
engineering  firms  that  had  previously  conducted  administrative  studies  for 
that  department.  The  Department  of  Agriculture  brought  back  on  a  part- 
time  basis  a  former  official  turned  college  president  to  head  up  a  reorgani- 
zation program.  The  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  has  used  the 
services  of  a  number  of  consultants  to  assist  on  its  own  internal  problems 
as  well  as  its  work  of  aiding  other  agencies  in  solving  theirs. 

At  the  state  and  local  levels,  the  Public  Administration  Service  has 
applied  on  a  broad  scale  this  idea  of  quiet  assistance  to  officials  in  the  in- 
stallation of  new  organization  and  methods.  This  approach  has  proved 
more  effective  in  most  cases  than  the  preparation  of  lengthy  survey  reports 
which  often  end  up  gathering  dust  in  bookcases.  In  many  areas,  local  and 
state  official^  secure  help  in  solving  their  problems  from  university  research 
bureaus.  The  Bureaus  of  Public  Administration  of  the  Universities  of 
Alabama,  California,  and  Virginia,  for  instance,  have  been  called  on  ex- 
tensively by  public  authorities  for  such  assistance. 

Use  of  Committees.  The  use  of  committees  of  subordinates  JS_JUIJQ& 
device  for  solving  administrative  groblems.  In  New  York  City,  for  example, 
Mayor  LaGuardia  appointed  a  Committee  on  Simplification  of  Procedures 
:omposed  of  the  budget  director  as  chairman,  the  comptroller,  the  Commis- 
sioner of  Investigation,  the  Commissioner  of  Purchase,  and  the  president 
of  the  Civil  Service  Commission.  In  the  federal  government,  the  War  Food 
Administrator  determined  upon  a  plan  of  reorganization  of  his  agency, 
and  appointed  a  committee  consisting  of  the  director  of  the  Office  of  Budget 
and  Finance  as  chairman,  the  director  of  personnel,  and  his  general  counsel 
to  put  the  plan  into  effect. 

Pointing  the  way  toward  increased  use  of  the  committee  device  in  the 
federal  government  are  two  other  recent  examples.  At  the  direction  of  the 


ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT  455 

deputy  chief  of  staff  of  the  War  Department,  two  committees  were  formed 
to  propose  improved  methods  for  reporting  on  the  strength  of  the  Army. 
One  of  these  committees— known  as  the  Steering  Committee— furnished 
the  general  leadership  and  considered  the  proposals  submitted  by  the  second 
committee — the  Working  Committee — which  assembled  the  study  data 
and  prepared  alternative  suggestions  for  better  strength  reporting. 

The  second  example  is  found  in  the  use  of  the  committee  device  to 
achieve  the  objectives  of  three  federal  agencies — the  General  Accounting 
Office,  the  Treasury  Department,  and  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget — in  bring- 
ing about  a  simplification  of  the  governmental  payroll  system.  Repre- 
sentatives of  each  of  these  agencies  collaborated  in  the  study,  preparation 
of  findings,  and  formulation  of  recommendations.  Following  approval  by 
the  three  agencies,  the  necessary  regulations  were  issued  by  each  for  its 
sphere  of  government-wide  responsibility  to  make  the  recommendations 
effective. 

Special  committees  are  not  only  a  useful  means  of  developing  new  ideas, 
but  are  often  helpful  when  it  comes  to  putting  the  ideas  into  effect.  The 
United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  has  used  such  committees  ex- 
tensively.11 But  there  are  dangers  as  well  as  advantages.  Committee  mem- 
bers may  already  be  overburdened  to  a  point  that  th$  proposed  course  of 
action  is  apt  to  be  no  more  well  thought  out  than  an  off-the-cuff  decision 
by  the  administrator.  The  two-committee  system  used  in  the  War  Depart- 
ment provides  a  method  for  lessening  such  a  danger. 

Sometimes  committees  are  appointed  to  meet  situations  in  which  the 
members  have  vested  interests,  so  that  no  neutral  or  over-all  viewpoint  can 
be  brought  to  bear  on  them.  Moreover,  the  designation  of  a  committee  is 
often  an  effort  to  compensate  for  the  failure  of  an  operating  official  or  for 
inadequate  staff  work.  Committees  are  most  fruitful  when  an  admin- 
istrative assistant  or  a  member  of  the  administrator's  general  staff  functions 
as  chairman  or  services  the  committee  through  the  collection  of  information 
and  the  preparation  of  draft  reports. 

Staff  Meetings.  Meetings  of  the  administrator^with  bis  principal  assist- 
ants can  be  of  greaF  value  In  administrative  self-improvement.1"  Such 
meetings  are  in  general  more  productive  in  providing  a  forum  for  the 
common  recognition  of  deficiencies  and  for  bringing  about  general  agree- 
ment on  a  course  of  action  than  in  evolving  specific  solutions.  By  careful 
planning,  the  administrator  can  center  attention  upon  the  most  important 
points  and  make  certain  that  the  discussion  does  not  reduce  itself  to  ir- 
relevant issues. 

11 C/.  Glaser,  Comstock,  "Managing  Committee  Work  in  a  Large  Organization,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  249  ff. 

12  Cf.  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "Policy  Formulation  and  the  Administrative  Process,"  Amer- 
ican Political  Science  Review,  1939,  Vol.  33,  p.  55  ff.  Cf.  also  above  Ch.  4,  "Democratic 
Administration,"  sec.  5,  "Office  Democracy." 


456  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

Staff  meetings  are  successful  only  when  problems  of  interest  to  all  are 
on  the  agenda.  Accordingly,  at  a  meeting  of  an  agency  head  with  his 
bureau  or  division  chiefs,  it  would  be  fruitful  to  discuss  means  of  better 
work-programming  and  budgeting  throughout  the  agency  or  a  new  plan 
for  providing  legal  services  to  all  the  subdivisions.  Intensive  consideration 
of  the  internal  organization  of  one  of  the  subdivisions  or  the  revision  of 
technical  procedures  affecting  only  two  or  three  would  not  hold  the  atten- 
tion of  the  whole  group.  On  the  other  hand,  frcflueaL.|nectings  dqjgive 
the  governmental  executive  an  opportunity  to  develop  team  spirit  and  to 
bring  about  a  union  of  minds  among  his  key  men.  This  is  essential  to  an 
institutional  environment  productive  of  management  improvement. 

Role  of  the  Administrative  General  Staff.  The  general  staff  officers  or 
units  inevitably  bear  the  brunt  in  analyzing  complex  problems  of  organi- 
zation and  procedure  and  in  developing  solutions.  The  term  "adminis- 
trative general  staff"  refers  only  to  those  staff  officers  or  units  that  share 
with  the  agency  executive  his  problems  of  management  and  deal  with 
matters  which  he  must  resolve  as  the  head  of  the  organization.  This  would 
include  those  concerned  with  program  planning,  budgeting,  administrative 
planning,  and  personnel  management.  It  would  exclude  for  the  most  part 
such  activities  as  routine  legal  service,13  purchasing,  accounting,  plant  main- 
tenance, and  other  general  services  which,  while  of  great  importance  to  the 
effective  functioning  of  the  organization,  are  essentially  of  an  auxiliary  or 
service  character  rather  than  aids  in  general  management. 

In  small  organizations  and  on  the  lower  operating  levels  of  a  large 
organization,  the  directing  official  can  do  most  of  his  staff  work  himself 
or  with  the  aid  of  a  deputy  or  administrative  assistant.  As  the  problems 
of  administration  increase  in  complexity,  he  will  require  full-time  staff  offi- 
cers of  the  type  mentioned,  and  in  addition  one  or  more  personal  assistants. 
These  general  staff  units,  as  the  planning,  programming,  analyzing,  deploy- 
ing, and  coordinating  arms  of  the  administrator,  have  a  vital  role  to  play  in 
bringing  about  improvement  in  the  agency's  internal  arrangements. 

The  budget  office,  for  example,  in  the  formulation  of  work  plans  with 
the  operating  bureaus  or  divisions  deals  with  two  general  classes  of  prob- 
lems: first,  the  character  and  extent  of  operations  that  are  proposed — that  is 
to  say,  the  program;  second,  the  organization  and  methods  to  carry  out 
that  program.  Insofar  as  the  budget  staff  has  true  understanding  of  ad- 
ministrative matters,  it  will  be  able  to  raise  the  general  level  of  manage- 
ment. Because  of  this  interrelationship  of  budgeting  and  administrative 
planning,  the  two  are  often  combined  under  the  same  head.  If  separate, 
the  two  groups  must  work  together  very  closely. 

The  personnel  office  can  be  a  potent  factor  in  improving  administration. 

13  For  a  discussion  of  the  potential  contribution  of  legal  officers  to  the  work  of  the  ad- 
ministrative general  staff,  see  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "The  Lawyer's  Role  in  Public  Administra- 
tion," Yale  Law  Journal,  1946,  Vol.  55,  p.  498  ff.  Cf.  also  below  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test." 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  457 


Staffing  the  organization  with  qualifkdjDei^jQ^^^ 

securing  efficient  operation.  More  germane,  however,  to  our  subject  here 
isntorrspp'orliunity  the  personnel  office  has  of  uncovering  organizational  and 
operating  difficulties  in  the  course  of  its  daily  contacts  with  operating  offi- 
cials and  individual  employees.  The  position-classification  analyst  is  in  a 
strategic  spot  to  identify  administrative  problems  because  he  looks  into  the 
content  of  specific  jobs  and  their  place  in  the  organization.  Employee- 
relations  staff  can  often  locate  trouble  areas  in  dealing  with  grievances  and 
other  personal  problems.  A  regular  duty,  therefore,  of  the  personnel  office 
is  to  call  to  the  attention  of  the  budget  or  administrative-planning  office 
any  internal  defects  which  it  discovers  in  its  daily  work. 

An  administrative-planning  office  providing  facilities  for  the  diagnosis 
and  remedy  of  major  ills  of  organization  and  method  is  an  essential  part 
of  the  administrative  general  staff  of  city,  county,  state,  or  nation,  or  of  a 
large  operating  subdivision.  The  following  excerpt  from  the  order  estab- 
lishing a  division  of  management  planning  in  the  Office  of  Departmental 
Administration  of  the  State  Department  in  Washington  illustrates  the  type 
of  activities  which  are  appropriate  for  such  a  unit  : 

(1)  Continuous  study  of  our  foreign  policies  and  objectives  in  the 
light  of  trends  in  foreign  and  domestic  affairs,  and  participation  in  plan- 
ning future  foreign  relations  programs,  with  particular  reference  to  the 
administrative  implications  and  feasibility  of  such  programs,  and  with 
a  view  to  developing  and  executing  administrative  management  policies 
fully  adjusted  to  the  Department's  changing  needs. 

(2)  Furnishing  of  advisory  and  consultative  services  and  assistance  in 
a  staff  capacity  to  divisions  and  offices  to  facilitate  the  carrying  out  of 
their  assigned  functions  through  the  planned  improvement  of  manage- 
ment. 

(3)  Continuous  study  of  improved  techniques  of  management  an- 
alysis and  planning  in  government  and  industry  with  a  view  to  the  ap- 
plication of  such  techniques  to  the  improvement  of  management  in  the 
Department. 

(4)  Continuous   appraisal   of   the   Department's  organizational   and 
functional  relations  with  other  governmental  and  with  intergovernmental 
agencies,  including  interdepartmental  and  intergovernmental  commit- 
tees or  similar  organized  groups,  with  particular  reference  to  over-all 
administrative  implications  for  the  Department,  and  with  a  view  to  the 
continuous  development  of  improved  working  understandings. 

(5)  Collaboration  with  the  planning  staff  of  the  Office  of  the  Foreign 
Service  in  studying  problems  of  mutual  interest  and  concern  with  a  view 
to  the  development  of  sound  over-all  administrative  policies  and  prac- 
tices and  more  effective  working  relations  between  organizational  units 
of  the  Department,  other  agencies,  and  the  Foreign  Service. 

(6)  Investigation,  analysis  and  appraisal  of  the  effectiveness  of  the 
Department's  organization  structure,  including  its  component  divisions 
and   offices   and   intradepartmental   committees   or   similar   organized 
groups,  with  a  view  to  the  development  of  new  organization  units  or  to 
such  adjustments  of  organizational  structure  as  may  be  required  for  the 
effective  implementation  of  present  and  future  responsibilities. 


458  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

(7)  Analysis  of  functions  and  of  work  assignments  and  lines  of  au- 
thority and  responsibility  among  the  component  offices  and  divisions  of 
the  Department  with  a  view  to  clearer  definitions  as  required  and  maxi- 
mum coordination  of  effort  based  on  exact  understanding  of  working 
relations. 

(8)  Study  and  analysis  of  work  methods  and  procedures,  with  par- 
ticular reference  to  those  which  cut  across  organizational  lines  in  the  de- 
partment, and  between  the  Department  and  other  agencies,  such  as  the 
flow  of  correspondence  and  other  documentation,  with  a  view  to  work 
simplification,  standardization  of  methods  and  procedures,  elimination  of 
waste  time  and  effort,  reduction  of  costs  or  delays,  and  improved  utiliza- 
tion of  employee  skills,  and  review  and  control  of  forms  with  a  view  to 
their  standardization  and  simplification. 

(9)  Preparation,  or  assistance  in  the  preparation,  and  review  (a)  of 
proposed  legislation  or  executive  orders  concerning  the  authority,  func- 
tions or  management  of  the  Department  and  (b)  of  departmental  orders 
and  regulations,  administrative  instructions,  organizational  and  admin- 
istrative manuals,  and  other  documents  concerning  organizational  struc- 
ture, functions,  lines  of  authority  and  responsibility,  work  methods  and 
procedures,  and  the  designation  of  ranking  officers  of  the  Department 
and  of  the  Department's  representatives  on  interdepartmental  committees 
and  similar  agencies.    The  Division  of  Management  Planning  shall  be 
responsible  for  necessary  clearances  of  such  documents  with  interested 
divisions  and  offices,  and  all  such  documents,  prior  to  issuance,  shall  be 
cleared  with  the  Division  of  Management  Planning,  which  shall  examine 
them  from  the  viewpoint  of  content  and  purpose,  their  over-all  adminis- 
trative implications  and  effects,  conformity  with  previously  issued  docu- 
ments of  similar  character,  and  conformity  with  existing  regulations  on 
the  subject,  such  as  those  set  forth  in  Departmental  Order  1269  of  May 
3,  1944. 

(10)  Assistance  in  the  development  of  a  system  of  divisional  progress 
reports  and,  through  study  of  such  reports,  keeping  informed  on  current 
accomplishments  and  trends  in  program  activity  as  a  basis  for  anticipat- 
ing, where  possible,  need  for  adjustments  in  organization,  clarification  of 
functions  and  of  lines  of  authority  and  responsibility,  and  improvement 
in  work  methods  and  procedures. 

(11)  Enlisting  the  active  support  and  assistance  of  all  employees  in 
the   improvement   of  management    in   the   Department   through    such 
means  as  the  development  of  employee  suggestion  and  incentive  pro- 
grams, employee-management  conferences  and  the  like. 

(12)  Participation  with  the  Division  of  Budget  and  Finance  in  the 
consideration  of  such  matters  as  the  preparation  of  budget  estimates  and 
the  allotment  of  positions,  with  the  Division  of  Departmental  Personnel 
in  the  consideration  of  such  matters  as  job  evaluation  and  classification, 
with  the  Division  of  Administrative  Service  in  the  consideration  of  such 
matters  as  the  allotment  and  utilization  of  space  and  equipment,  and 
with  the  Division  of  Communications  and  Records  in  the  consideration 
of  such  matters  as  problems  of  record  administration;  keeping  those  di- 
visions currently  informed  concerning  management  planning  matters 
which  may  affect  their  work  and  securing  their  advice  and  assistance  in 
the  conduct  of  management  planning  projects  and  in  effecting  manage- 
ment improvements. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT'  459 

The  role  of  an  administrative-planning  or  administrative-management 
unit  is  also  indicated  in  the  following  sentences  from  a  specimen  draft  of 
an  order  developed  by  the  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  for  the 
guidance  of  agencies  interested  in  setting  up  such  an  office: 

The  Administrative  Management  Office  will  give  continuous  and  sus- 
tained attention  to  the  improvement  of  organization  structure  and  the 
development  of  sound  administrative  practices  in  both  the  departmental 
and  regional  offices,  for  the  purpose  of  facilitating  and  expediting  over- 
all direction,  coordination,  and  control  of  the  Department's  administra- 
tive activities. 

.  .  .  The  Director  of  the  Administrative  Management  Office  will  serve 
the  Administrator  in  a  purely  advisory  and  consultative  capacity  and  will 
not  have  any  authority  nor  responsibility  for  direct  operations. 

.  .  .  The  Director  of  the  Administrative  Management  Office  will.  .  . 
work  closely  with  the  personnel,  budget,  program  planning,  research, 
and  statistical  directors  in  the  formulation  and  revision  of  organizational 
structure,  budget  estimates,  personnel  classifications,  and  related  matters 
resulting  from  any  important  shift  in  emphasis  or  direction  of  the 
agency's  activities. 

Types  of  Administrative-Planning  Offices.  The  City  and  County  of 
Los  Angeles  long  stood  at  the  head  of  the  list  of  governmental  units  having 
administrative-planning  offices.  The  Bureau  of  Budget  and  Efficiency  of  the 
city  and  the  Bureau  of  Administrative  Research — originally  Bureau  of 
Efficiency — of  the  county  were  the  forerunners  of  a  number  of  such  offices 
set  up  in  state  and  local  government.  On  the  whole,  however,  munici- 
palities, counties,  and  states  have  lagged  behind  in  incorporating  into  their 
general-staff  structure  specific  facilities  for  this  important  work. 

The  federal  government  affords  scores  of  examples  of  organized  admin- 
istrative-planning work,  not  only  at  the  top  level  of  agencies  but  also  in 
their  bureaus  and  divisions.  The  Division  of  Administrative  Planning  of 
the  Farm  Credit  Administration  and  the  Division  of  Coordination  and 
Procedures  of  the  Social  Security  Board  were  early  and  noteworthy  examples. 
The  Post  Office  Department  has  established  a  Budget  and  Administrative 
Unit  in  the  immediate  office  of  the  Postmaster  General.  This  unit  has  two 
branches:  budget  work,  handled  by  a  Budgeting  Commissioner;  and  admin- 
istrative planning,  headed  by  a  Commissioner  of  Administrative  Planning. 

The  Commerce  Department  has  an  Office  of  Budget  and  Management, 
reporting  to  the  executive  assistant  to  the  Secretary  of  Commerce.  In  a 
recent  reorganization  of  the  Veterans  Administration,  provision  was  made 
for  an  Office  of  Coordination  and  Planning,  which  includes  several  sub- 
divisions known  as  services — research  service,  administrative-management 
service,  inspection  and  investigation  service,  budget  and  planning  service, 
and  employee-suggestion  service.  Nearly  all  of  the  emergency  agencies  of 
World  War  II  found  a  need  for  central  staff  to  help  the  top  executive  work 
out  the  agency's  organization  structure,  define  the  functions  and  respon- 


460  ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

sibilities  of  its  various  subdivisions,  establish  devices  for  coordination  and 
control,  and  develop  general  plans  of  management  and  operating  practices 
governing  the  entire  enterprise. 

The  use  of  administrative-planning  staffs  by  the  Army  and  Navy  has 
been  particularly  significant.14  When  General  Somervell  was  appointed 
commanding  general  of  the  Army  Service  Forces,  he  organized  a  Control 
Division  as  his  principal  arm  to  work  out  solutions  to  organizational,  op- 
erating, and  procedural  problems.  The  Control  Division  was  subdivided 
into  three  branches:  (1)  a  statistical  branch,  which  supervised  the  reporting 
systems  of  ASF,  analyzing  and  making  special  reports  on  progress  and 
operations;  (2)  an  administrative-management  branch,  which  investigated 
a  wide  range  of  administrative  problems,  conducted  surveys,  and  supervised 
work-simplification  and  work-measurement  programs  carried  on  through- 
out all  subdivisions  of  ASF;  and  (3)  a  procedures  branch,  which  developed 
and  exercised  general  control  over  ASF  personnel,  procurement,  supply,  and 
fiscal  procedures. 

A  Management  Control  Directorate,  established  in  1942  under  the  re- 
organization of  the  Army  Air  Forces,  carried  out  many  of  these  same 
activities  and  proved  a  valuable  means  of  improving  and  simplifying  ad- 
ministrative arrangements  and  of  establishing  machinery  to  execute  new 
programs.  While  no  formal  administrative-planning  unit  has  been  estab- 
lished at  the  General  Staff  level  of  the  Army,  informal  assistance  of  this 
kind  has  been  utilized  to  some  extent.  No  real  provision  for  it  has  been 
made  at  the  level  of  the  Secretary  of  War,  although  some  such  work  has 
been  done  by  the  Office  of  Civilian  Personnel  in  the  Secretary's  office.15 

In  the  Navy,  on  the  other  hand,  the  Secretary  in  1942  set  up  an  Office 
of  the  Management  Engineer  to  assist  him  on  problems  of  organization, 
distribution  of  functions,  administrative  relationships,  procedures,  and  meth- 
ods. This  office  conducted  organizational  and  procedural  studies,  developed 
standards  for  measuring  administrative  activities,  and  promoted  improved 
utilization  of  manpower.  Realizing  not  only  that  the  central  office  could 
handle  merely  a  small  part  of  the  agency's  work  of  analysis  and  adjustment, 
but  also  that  it  should  be  placed  as  close  to  operations  as  possible,  the  office 
has  encouraged  the  various  bureaus  of  the  Navy  to  establish  staff  facilities 
of  their  own.  As  a  result,  administrative-planning  units  have  grown  up  in 
many  places  throughout  the  organization. 

Harold  D.  Smith,  upon  taking  office  in  1939  as  director  of  the  United 
States  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  established  a  Division  of  Administrative  Man- 

14  Cf.   the  symposia  on   "Administrative  Management  in  the  Army  Service  Forces"  by 
Somervell,  Brehon  and  Others,  and  on  "Administrative  Problems  in  Naval  Procurement  and 
Logistics"   by   Forrestal,   James  and   Others,  Public  Administration  Review,   1944,  Vol.  4,  p. 
255  ff.,  and  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  289  ff. 

15  For  an  excellent  general  discussion  of  some  of  the  basic  problems,  see  Nelson,  Otto  L., 
Jr.,   "Wartime  Developments  in  War  Department  Organization  and  Administration,"  Public 
Administration  Review,  1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  1  ff. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  461 

agemcnt  to  provide  central  administrative-planning  activities  as  part  of 
the  general  staff  facilities  of  the  chief  executive.  One  of  the  first  programs 
of  the  newly  organized  division  was  designed  to  bring  forth  and  strengthen 
administrative-planning,  budgeting,  and  personnel  offices  in  all  government 
agencies.  All  of  the  bureau's  divisions — Estimates,  Legislative  Reference, 
Statistical  Standards,  and  Fiscal,  as  well  as  Administrative  Management — 
have  a  share  in  bringing  about  administrative  improvement  throughout  the 
federal  government.  However,  primary  responsibility  for  organizational 
matters  and  for  finding  answers  to  administrative  problems  falls  within  the 
specific  sphere  of  the  Administrative  Management  Division.16  A  staff 
instruction  of  this  division  defines  its  function  as  follows : 

The  Division  of  Administrative  Management  is  generally  responsible, 
as  a  part  of  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  for  assisting  the  President  in 
bringing  about  better  organization  and  management  of  the  Federal 
Government.  It  does  this  through  bringing  about  a  better  distribution 
of  functions  within  and  among  Federal  agencies,  helping  with  the  estab- 
lishment of  new  agencies  and  liquidating  old  ones,  assisting  individual 
agencies  on  administrative  problems,  strengthening  agency  staff  services, 
improving  government-wide  business  practices  and  procedures,  and  re- 
viewing the  administrative  aspects  of  proposed  legislation  and  executive 
orders.  A  major  emphasis  is  the  development  of  programs  which  are  of 
help  to  government  departments  and  agencies  in  solving  their  own 
problems. 

Tasfo  of  Line  Operators  and  Supervisors.  Line  operators  and  super- 
visors have  the  primary  responsibility  for  administrative  improvement.17 
Preoccupation  with  the  work  of  management  staffs  has  generally  led  ob- 
servers to  overlook  this  fact.  The  operator  is  the  one  who  is  apt  to  know 
first  that  things  are  not  going  well,  and  who  must  make  any  new  solution 
work.  Tuning  up  the  organization,  making  informal  adjustments  here  and 
there,  and  changing  methods  are  all  part  of  the  day's  management  chores. 

Whether  or  not  the  operator  does  a  good  job  in  organizing  the  functions 
under  his  supervision  and  in  getting  all  the  pieces  to  mesh  together  will 
depend  upon  his  interest  and  knowledge.  Many  become  absorbed  in  the 
substantive  or  technical  phases  of  their  work  and  are  less  interested  in,  or 
at  least  unconscious  of,  the  fact  that  their  job  is  in  large  part  an  administra- 
tive one. 

The  question  may  well  be  raised:  Where  does  the  role  of  the  operator 
break  off  and  that  of  the  general  staff  begin?  Unfortunately,  there  is  no 
clear-cut  answer.  The  operator  who  has  many  organizational  or  proce- 

16  For  a  study  of  the  intertwining  of  budgetary  and  managerial  staff  work  on  the  central 
level  of  the  federal  government,  see  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "The  Bureau  of  the  Budget:  Its 
Evolution  and  Present  Role,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  p.  653  ff.t 
869  ff.    See  also  below  Ch.  25,  "Fiscal  Accountability,"  sec.  3,  "Budgetary  Coordination." 
Harold  D.  Smith's  work  philosophy  has  been  set  forth  in  his  book  The  Management  of  Your 
Government.  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1945. 

17  See  above  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision." 


462  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

dural  problems  will — or  in  any  event  should — have  an  assistant  or  a  staff 
unit  of  his  own  to  work  on  them.  He  may  attempt  to  resolve  those  questions 
which  cannot  be  settled  within  his  own  division  by  raising  them  with  people 
in  the  other  divisions,  but  usually  at  this  point  the  issue  is  found  to  contain 
elements  which  require  more  intensive  study  than  he  can  give.  Such  more 
difficult  problems  will  rise  up  in  the  organization  as  a  daily  occurrence. 
Here  it  is  that  the  higher  administrative-planning  staff  enters  the  picture. 

By  providing  useful  service  to  the  operators,  the  central  staff  will  create 
a  good  market  for  its  special  competence  and  will  not  have  to  rely  primarily 
upon  orders  from  the  top  executive.  It  is  best  not  to  look  at  administrative- 
planning  units  or  any  of  the  general-staff  offices  as  control  centers  or  to 
require  a  large  mass  of  detailed  matters  to  be  cleared  through  them.  In 
fact,  a  check-and-review  approach  will  defeat  general-staff  work. 

Role  of  the  Ran\  and  File.  What  has  been  said  here  about  the  need  of 
participation  by  the  operator  and  supervisor  in  management  improvement 
applies  also  to  the  body  of  employees.  Employees  know  when  things  go 
wrong.  They  are  in  a  position  to  see  how  detailed  situations  can  be  im- 
proved and  where  new  methods  will  provide  more  efficient  results.  Unless 
their  ideas  and  suggestions  are  captured,  the  organization  will  lose  one  of 
its  major  sources  of  help. 

Employee  suggestions  will  not  be  made,  nor  will  teamwork  among 
employees  in  improving  operations  be  secured,  unless  supervisors  furnish 
incentive.  Formal  employee-suggestion  systems18  are  valuable.  However, 
they  are  incidental  to  the  larger  problem  of  good  supervision  and 
foremanship. 

Most  first-line  supervisors  do  not  have  time  for  extensive  training  or  to 
explore  and  experiment  in  these  fields  on  their  own.  Yet  they  need  to  have 
a  grasp  of  some  of  the  elementary  aspects  of  analysis  and  some  of  the 
specific  work-simplification  techniques  suitable  for  their  own  tasks.  To 
meet  this  need  in  the  federal  government,  numerous  agencies  have  devel- 
oped special  training  and  improvement  programs  for  particular  or  con- 
tinued use.19 

3.   TECHNIQUES  FOR  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

Mission  of  the  Administrator.  Experience  in  government  as  in  industry 
has  shown  clearly  that  we  cannot  expect  better  organization  and  manage- 
ment than  is  suggested  by  the  quality  o^ j^sonncHn.j^dministrative  posts. 
New  constitutions,  statutes,  anocharters  might  be  adoptecT  which  provide 
for  streamlined  structure  and  method,  and  yet  results  might  be  negligible. 
There  is  the  famous  illustration  of  one  state  which  adopted  a  compre- 

18  Sec  above  Ch.   19,   "The  Art  of  Supervision,"   sec.   4,   "Supervision  and   Employee 
Initiative." 

19  For  a  fuller  discussion  of  some  of  these,  see  above  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,'* 
sec.  2,  "The  Supervisory  Skills." 


ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT  463 

hensivc  reorganization  plan,  but  continued  to  function  as  before.  Nothing 
is  accomplished  except  as  ideas  or  plans  are  translated  into  action.  Action 
requires  administration. 

One  of  the  mistakes  of  the  early  government  reformers  was  the  assump- 
tion that  once  a  good  setup  had  been  established  and  competent  officials 
placed  in  office,  all  would  work  smoothly  from  then  on.  How  different 
is  the  fact!  Administration  is  dynamic;  organizational  arrangements  and 
relationships  are  continually  in  flux.  Structure  must  be  constantly  adjusted 
to  meet  changes  in  program,  policy,  product,  methods,  and  human  beings. 
This  is  why  the  development  of  the  Public  Administration  Clearing  House 
and  the  large  number  of  professional  organizations  of  public  officials  as 
depositories  of  work  experience  is  so  significant. 

Public  leadership  and  the  support  ol  sound  policy  and  program  are 
essential  "a  tithe  higher  administrative  posts.  It  is  the  organization,  however, 
which  produces  public  services  and  carries  out  public  purposes.  Conse- 
quently, it  is  imperative  to  have  administrators  who  will  inculcate  in  their 
entire  establishment  a  recognition  that  continuous  readjustment  in  structure 
and  method  is  a  task  in  which  all  have  a  common  stake. 

A  general  feeling  that  something  is  wrong  with  the  operating  machinery 
of  an  agency  is  of  no  value  unless  it  is  translated  into  specifics  of  exactly 
what  is  wrong  and  precisely  how  it  can  be  remedied.  The  administrator  may 
notice  that  papers  reflecting  internal  conflicts  or  confusions  are  crossing  his 
desk  in  increasing  numbers.  He  may  observe  that  newspapers  blast  his 
operations  because  they  are  bogging  down.  His  political  superiors  may  bring 
program  failures  to  his  attention.  He  may  grow  aware  that  his  staff  is 
transitory,  with  an  unusually  high  turnover.  He  may  begin  to  question 
apparent  contradictions  of  reports  on  financial  or  program  status,  or  to 
note  that  contradictory  regulations  have  been  issued  by  his  staff.  These 
are  only  a  few  of  the  obvious  ways  in  which  the  administrator  may  be 
roused  into  considering  remedies.  How  does  he  proceed  from  this  point? 

It  is  well  to  recall  that  the  administrator  has  several  major  concerns.20 
He  must  define  the  objectives  of  his  program.  He  must  determine  how 
things  are  to  be  done — that  is,  the  division  of  labor  and  the  allocation  of 
responsibility.  He  is  concerned  also  with  quantity — how  much  is  to  be 
done;  with  rate  of  service — how  fast  things  are  to  be  done;  with  quality — 
how  well  they  are  to  be  done;  with  staffing — who  is  to  do  it;  and  with  cost. 
He  must  communicate  his  ideas  so  that  all  employees  will  know  what  is 
expected  of  them,  and  he  must  provide  for  lateral  exchange  of  knowledge 
so  that  each  employee  will  know  generally  what  other  employees  and  units 
are  doing.  He  must  set  up  controls  to  ensure  that  the  program  he  wants  is 
being  carried  out  in  the  manner  he  wants  it  carried  out  and  that  this  is 
being  done  as  expeditiously  and  efficiently  as  possible. 

20  Sec  Stone,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  10.   Cf.  also  above  Ch.  9,  "The  Departmental  System," 
sec.  3,  "The  Secretary's  Business." 


464  ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

The  factors  which  contribute  to  the  smooth  running  of  his  organization, 
together  with  that  indefinable  ability  to  motivate  others  which  some  officials 
have,  will  be  of  no  value  if  they  are  neglected  or  never  recognized.  The 
administrator  will,  then,  find  it  desirable  to  look  for  a  continuously  opera- 
tive indicator — giving  warning  prior  to  general  complaints — that  will  let 
him  know  when  his  organization  is  not  producing.  He  will  want  to  use 
critical,  evaluative,  and  systematic  introspection  with  regard  to  what  his 
organization  is  doing  and  how  it  is  doing  it.  He  will  want  to  keep  the 
parts  oiled  and  closely  geared  together. 

Such  introspection  must  rely  on  what  is  called  the  survey  method.  Put 
another  way,  all  administrative  review  and  improvement  of  operations  is 
dependent  upon  some  fact-finding  method.  If  the  administrator  suspects 
that  the  state  of  morale  of  his  employees  is  such  that  operations  are  im- 
paired, he  should  first  ascertain  the  cause.  If  he  discovers  that  work  is 
piling  up,  he  must  locate  the  cause  of  the  backlog. 

Whether  the  fact-finding  method  is  used  by  the  administrator  himself, 
a  committee,  the  staff  meeting,  line  supervisors,  general-staff  experts,  or  out- 
side consultants  is  relatively  unimportant.  Irrespective  of  who  collects  the 
facts,  the  method  of  assembling  them  is  common  to  each  approach.  But 
there  must  be  collection  of  information  or  data.  The  process  must  be 
planned.  It  must  be  organized  and  lead  to  analysis.  Conclusions  must  be 
reached,  and  a  new  policy  or  a  plan  of  action  for  better  organization  or 
method  must  be  developed.  The  proposals  should  finally  be  tested  and 
installed.  Virtually  the  only  preference  between  the  various  methods  of 
fact-finding  lies  in  the  intensity  with  which  the  analysis  can  be  made. 
For  all  this  the  basic  device  is  the  administrative  survey. 

Types  of  Administrative  Surveys.  The  plan  for  the  administrative  sur- 
vey will  depend  materially  upon  the  type  of  fact-finding  to  be  undertaken. 
It  may  require  several  varieties  of  special  analytical  techniques,  depending 
upon  the  purpose  of  the  appraisal.  Three  types  merit  attention  here. 

(1)  The  reconnaissance  survey.  This  is  a  diagnostic  device  to  identify 
administrative  difficulties,  and  is  an  inevitable  preliminary  to  all  other  types 
of  surveys.  It  may  be  long  or  short,  depending  upon  the  familiarity  of  the 
analysts  with  the  function  or  activity  being  surveyed.  The  object  of  the 
reconnaissance  is  to  arrive  at  an  early  conclusion  as  to  whether  additional 
fact-finding  is  necessary,  and  of  what  sort;  or  whether  action  can  be  taken 
immediately,  and  of  what  sort.  It  requires  careful  planning,  for  recon- 
naissance generally  should  be  brief  and  touch  upon  only  the  necessary  high 
spots.  It  should  not  be  permitted  to  linger  over  details. 

The  interview  is  the  principal  method  employed.  Pertinent  workload 
and  production  figures,  written  statements  of  functions  and  operating  meth- 
ods, organization  charts,  record  forms,  and  available  statistical  data  may  be 
compiled  during  the  interview  process.  Organization  and  analysis  of  mate- 


ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT  465 

rial  must  be  undertaken  with  the  recognition  that  basic  problems,  not  details, 
are  sought  to  be  identified. 

(2)  The  over-all  survey.   This  is  analogous  to  a  complete  checjs-up  jof 
i  complex  machine.  It  deals  with  all  the  elements  with  which  management 
is  concerned,  from  policy  through  organization  and  staffing '  dbwBMtojdte 
tailed  procedure.   Examples  of  this  sort  of  project  are  surveys  which  were 
made  by  the  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  of  the  Bituminous  Coal 
Commission   and   the  Civil   Aeronautics   Administration;   by  the  Public 
Administration  Service  of  the  states  of  North  Dakota  and  South  Carolina, 
Montgomery  County,  Ohio,  and  the  town  of  Brookline,  Massachusetts;  by 
the  Bureau  of  Public  Administration  of  the  State  of  Virginia;  by  the  Brook- 
ings  Institution  of  the  state  of  North  Carolina;  and  by  the  Los  Angeles 
County  Bureau  of  Budget  and  Efficiency  of  the  county's  operations.  It  may 
employ  the  reconnaissance  approach  in  some  areas  and  detailed  analyses 
in  others. 

(3)  The  special-purpose  survey.  The  scope  of  this  surveyjijay  be  based 
upon  the  results  of  a  preliminary  reconnaissance  survey,  or  it  may  be  de- 
cided in  advance,  prior  to  any  effort  at  fact-finding.  Usually  it  will  involve 
either  an  organizational  survey,  a  survey  of  some  specific  function,  or  a 
procedure  survey.    The  organizational  survey  is  limited  to  structure  and 
allocation  of  functions.    It  usually  emphasizes  top-organization  considera- 
tions.  The  functional  survey  traces  some  function  through  all  of  its  rami- 
fications across  organizational  lines.  It  may  run  the  gamut  from  plans  and 
objectives  through  organization  and  method  with  respect  to  a  particular 
function. 

The  procedure  survey  picks  up  at  the  operating  level,  and  is  normally 
tied  to  some  function — for  instance,  personnel,  purchasing,  accounting,  or 
public  works.  It  is  not  aimed  at  objectives  and  organization.  The  Navy 
Department,  through  its  Management  Engineer's  Office,  has  carried  on  an 
interesting  combination  of  procedural  and  personnel  survey  designed  to 
identify  cases  of  nonutilization  of  employee  skills,  correct  allocation  of  posi- 
tions, and  eliminate  unnecessary  procedures  and  positions.  These  personnel- 
utilization  surveys  were  conducted  by  expert  analysts  in  each  bureau  on  a 
sectional  basis;  that  is,  each  organizational  section  was  surveyed  as  an  entity, 
and  recommendations  were  submitted  before  the  team  moved  on. 

Some  of  the  methods  of  conducting  administrative  analysis  have  been 
well  understood  for  years  by  specialists  in  the  field,  but  very  little  of  this 
knowledge  has  been  brought  together  in  organized  form.  Administrative- 
survey  reports  provide  much  of  the  best  literature  available,  but  practically 
no  generalization  has  been  derived  from  these  individual  experiences  as  far 
as  methods  of  analysis  are  concerned.  The  one  comprehensive  effort  pub- 
lished to  date  is  Research  Methods  in  Public  Administration  by  John  M. 
Pfiffner.21  There  have  been  a  few  efforts  to  bring  together  the  story  on 

21  New  York:  Ronald,  1940. 


466  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

how  to  carry  out  special  kinds  of  administrative  studies,  particularly  the 
extended  discussion  of  methods  of  doing  classification  surveys  included  in 
the  1941  report  of  the  Civil  Service  Assembly  on  Position  Classification  in 
the  Public  Service.22  Much  experience  has  been  recorded  in  scientific-man- 
agement literature,  going  back  to  Frederick  W.  Taylor  and  the  Gilbreths, 
in  the  field  of  time  and  motion  study.23 

Reconnaissance.  As  a  preliminary  to  intensive  analysis,  reconnaissance 
should  lead  to  a  detailed  plan  of  action  as  quickly  as  possible.  This  kind 
of  reconnaissance  generally  starts  with  some  previous  indication  of  the  area 
of  attention  and  the  reasons  prompting  the  request  or  recommendation  for 
a  survey.  Steps  are  then  taken  to  obtain  a  more  specific  picture  of  the  area 
to  be  covered  and  the  problems  to  be  resolved. 

Whether,  in  all,  two  hours  or  two  weeks  are  to  be  spent  on  such  a  pre- 
view, the  objective  is  to  make  a  general  appraisal  of  the  operation  to  be 
analyzed.  This  may  include  any  or  all  of  the  following:  identifying  the 
nature  and  extent  of  activities;  noting  possible  variations  of  activities  from 
appropriation  purposes;  establishing  principal  manpower  demands;  making 
an  estimate  of  the  effectiveness  of  personnel  utilization;  sizing  up  manage- 
ment controls — administrative  reporting,  work  measurement,  cost  account- 
ing, inspections,  and  program-planning  facilities;  spotting  possible  organiza- 
tional or  procedural  weaknesses;  observing  the  quality  of  executive  leader- 
ship; and  taking  a  look  at  headquarters-field  relationships,  the  adequacy  of 
the  physical  plant,  the  degree  of  mechanization  of  clerical  processes,  the 
extent  of  the  backlog  of  work,  and  the  state  of  employee  relations. 

Before  a  decision  is  reached  that  this  preliminary  once-over  should  be 
followed  by  an  intensive  survey,  careful  weighing  must  take  place  of  the 
advantages  to  be  derived  against  the  investment  involved.  The  prospective 
gain  should,  of  course,  warrant  the  expenditure.  The  study  should  be  of 
greater  importance  than  alternative  survey  activities  that  might  be  under- 
taken, and  preferably  it  should  be  related  to  a  long-range  objective. 

When  reconnaissance  is  the  beginning  and  the  end  of  an  administrative 
analysis,  more  or  less  the  same  program  is  followed,  but  final  judgments 
are  made  and  recommendations  are  developed  on  the  spot.  It  then  becomes 
necessary  to  capitalize  on  the  knowledge  immediately  available.  Because 
intensive  study  is  precluded,  the  recommendations  should  usually  define  the 
basic  requirements,  rather  than  the  details,  of  administrative  reorganization 
or  managerial  improvement. 

Planning  the  Survey.  In  an  intensive  survey,  whatever  its  type,  the 
basic  elements  remain  more  or  less  constant.  Once  the  commitment  for  the 
study  has  been  made,  the  first  step  is  the  development  of  a  precise  plan  of 
work,  including  the  organizafion*ahd*scheduling  of  the  study.  This  faciIT- 

22  Chicago:  1941,  ch.  7. 

28  For  a  representative  work  in  this  field,  see  Barnes,  Ralph  M.,  Motion  and  Time  Study, 
2d  cdr  New  York:  Wiley,  1940. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  467 

tates  crystallization  of  the  problems  to  be  resolved.  Through  the  setting  up 
of  an  orderly  work  schedule  and  out  lining  of  tne  steps  that  must  be  taken,  it 
also  expedites  the  conducting  of  the  study.  Moreover,  the  work  plan  can 
be  a  great  aid  if  a  similar  study  is  later  undertaken  in  a  different  set  of  cir- 
cumstances, and  may  lead  to  a  standardized  approach  to  recurring  types  of 
studies. 

The  project  outline  should  include  a  brief  statement  of  the  problem  to  be 
analyzed,  the  objectives  of  the  study,  and  the  scope  of  the  work  to  be  under- 
taken. Issues  or  problems  likely  to  be  encountered  should  be  listed  as  pre- 
cisely as  possible.  The  individual  steps  to  be  taken  in  making  the  study 
should  be  set  out.  Sources,  documents,  and  authorities  to  be  consulted 
should  be  enumerated.  A  detailed  schedule  of  the  staff  requirements  should 
be  worked  out,  including  the  length  of  time  each  member  will  be  needed. 
The  approximate  date  of  completion,  not  only  of  each  major  step  in  the 
project  but  also  of  the  project  as  a  whole,  should  be  estimated  as  closely  as 
possible. 

In  selecting  staff  for  administrative  analysis,  it  is  important  that  there 
be  balance  among  the  types  of  skills  drawn  upon,  and  that  the  entire  staff 
— including  those  coopted  from  outside  the  surveying  agency — be  subject 
to  the  controls  of  the  leader  of  the  survey  group.  Advance  arrangements 
with  those  responsible  for  the  operations  to  be  surveyed  are  also  of  major 
importance  to  facilitate  the  work  and  working  relationships  of  the  project 
staff.  Ready  access  should  exist  to  the  top  official  who  is  in  a  position  to 
secure  acceptance  of  recommendations  in  the  area  to  be  surveyed.  The 
project  staff,  whether  outside  consultants  or  administrative-planning  per- 
sonnel of  the  agency,  will  find  it  desirable  to  arrange  for  some  degree  of 
assistance  by  the  budget  officer,  personnel  officer,  or  other  key  employees. 
It  may  be  necessary  for  the  staff  to  explain  the  project  to  top  officials,  and  to 
notify  or  explain  it  to  all  employees  in  order  to  ensure  their  understanding 
and  participation. 

Review  of  Written  Materials.  When  the  fact-gathering  stage  is  readied, 
the  choice  among  varying  approaches*  ahcf'difffcTeht  aids  an3  devices  is  al- 
most limitless.  It  is  at  this  point  that  the  analyst  must  use  his  skill  in.  deter- 
mining  those  most  appropriate  to  his_  purposes  _and  combining  or  adapting 
them  In  a  suitable  fashion.  Generally  the  starting  point  will  be  a  review  of 
written  materials,  including  statutes  and  orders,  which  give  the  historical 
background  of  the  organization.  The  survey  staff  must  also  secure  the  bene- 
fit of  any  previous  studies.  The  more  that  can  be  learned  about  the  business 
of  the  agency  or  the  unit  in  advance,  either  through  review  of  materials 
or  conversations  with  those  familiar  with  the  situation,  the  more  effectively 
will  the  subsequent  steps  of  the  survey  be  carried  out. 

The  study  of  constitutions,  statutes,  charters,  court  decisions,  executive 
orders,  instructions,  and  other  regulations  will  be  of  particular  significance  if 
inadequacies  or  inconsistencies  in  the  basic  mandate  are  the  primary  concern, 


468  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

or  if  it  is  known  what  changes  arc  to  be  made  and  the  job  is  to  revise 
the  legal  documents  accordingly.  Legal  materials,  however,  are  more  often 
than  not  a  scanty  resource  for  getting  at  the  more  specific  or  detailed  admin- 
istrative problems.  In  an  administrative  survey,  the  objective  is  more  likely 
to  be  a  diagnosis  of  what  is,  rather  than  what  ought  to  be  under  law  or 
regulation. 

Old  reports  and  administrative  documents,  legislative  hearings  and  de- 
bates, minutes  of  commission  or  board  meetings,  newspaper  accounts,  and 
published  treatise*  and  historical  records  as  well,  provide  useful  working 
material  in  acquiring  an  understanding  of  what  brought  about  a  particular 
organizational  arrangement  or  method  of  operation.  Such  materials  will 
usually  supply  only  part  of  the  picture,  however,  since  much  of  what  went 
on  before  may  never  have  been  recorded,  and  available  documents  not  in- 
frequently fail  to  tell  the  most  revealing  chapters  of  the  story.  Particular 
attention  should  be  given  to  any  earlier  studies  of  the  survey  area  and  to  any 
recommendations  that  may  have  been  developed  at  previous  times. 

Materials  reflecting  the  main  outlines  of  the  current  administrative  pic- 
ture should  always  be  given  a  careful  review  at  the  outset  of  a  survey.  These 
include  financial  and  activity  reports,  budget  justifications  and  hearings, 
work  programs,  and  organization  charts  and  manuals.  Such  records  as  job- 
classification  sheets,  other  personnel  data,  forms,  and  administrative  pre- 
scriptions of  one  sort  or  another  may  also  be  helpful. 

Questionnaires  and  Chect{  Lists.  When  secondary  sources  of  information 
have  been  exhausted  and  the  analyst  is  laying  plans  for  collection  of  detailed 
first-hand  data,  the  questionnaire  or  check-list  approach  is  likely  to  come  to 
mind.  This  is  a  useful  method  of  producing  information  quickly  from  a 
large  group  of  people  in  a  standardized  pattern.  It  also  contributes  to  build- 
ing up  an  accurate  and  complete  picture  by  providing  a  ready  check  of  one 
answer  against  another.  The  framing  of  significant  questions  in  advance 
and  in  detail,  however,  requires  an  appreciable  foundation  of  information  on 
the  agency  and  on  the  problems  being  covered. 

The  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  has  recently  made  considerable 
use  of  this  device  as  a  part  of  its  efforts  to  stimulate  management  improve- 
ment throughout  the  federal  government.  Early  in  1944,  a  pamphlet  en- 
titled An  Agency  Management  Program:  A  Guide  for  Self-Appraisal  and 
for  Planning  Economies  in  Operation  was  distributed  throughout  the  gov- 
ernment as  an  aid  to  agencies  in  sizing  up  their  operations.  The  pamphlet 
raised  questions  such  as  these:  What  is  our  attitude  toward  management? 
Are  all  of  our  activities  essential?  Are  we  well  organized?  What  have  we 
done  to  conserve  men,  money,  and  materials? 

A  year  later,  with  the  close  of  World  War  II  in  sight,  more  detailed 
schedules  were  developed  to  help  agencies  get  their  records  in  shape  in  an- 
ticipation of  liquidation  or  reduction  of  activities.  These  lists  of  questions 
were  directed  toward  the  evaluation  and  improvement  of  personnel  records 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  469 

and  controls,  fiscal  records  and  controls,  property  records  and  controls,  and 
record  management  and  controls.  Recently,  a  comprehensive  questionnaire 
on  agency  practices  was  prepared  and  distributed  in  connection  with  an 
analysis  of  the  administration  of  the  employee-retirement  system.  Its  use 
saved  untold  time  in  a  survey  covering  the  entire  federal  government. 

As  an  aid  in  interviews,  a  questionnaire  submitted  to  officials  in  advance 
will  prove  helpful  in  directing  their  attention  to  productive  topics.  It  will 
also  secure  greater  cooperation  by  permitting  advance  consideration  of  the 
questioner's  needs. 

Interviews.  While  much  has  been  written  about  interviewing,24  little 
material  is  available  on  the  use  of  the  interview  as  a  major  technique  in 
administrative  analysis.25  Careful  scheduling  and  conduct  of  interviews  can 
readily  provide  information,  insight,  and  ideas  that  are  otherwise  unobtain- 
able. Through  interviews,  it  is  possible  to  get  official  interpretation  of  the 
problems  under  study  and  ideas  on  their  solution;  clarify  questions  raised 
by  study  of  written  materials;  arrange  subsequent  contacts  with  subordi- 
nates; and  gain  understanding  of  personalities  and  attitudes  of  key  officials. 
When  good  coverage  through  interviews  has  been  obtained,  the  risk  of 
findings  and  recommendations  being  sidetracked  on  questions  of  fact  is  sub- 
stantially eliminated,  since  in  the  presentation  of  the  facts  the  operator's  point 
of  view  has  been  taken  into  account  and  potential  misunderstanding  has 
been  straightened  out  beforehand.  The  analyst  skilled  in  interviewing  can 
also  size  up  psychological  factors,  break  down  resistance  to  change,  and 
build  up  potential  support  for  forthcoming  proposals. 

Various  patterns  of  interviewing  may  be  employed.  In  reconnaissance 
or  in  the  general  course  of  analysis,  particularly  well-informed  and  com- 
municative individuals  can  be  spotted  and  listed  according  to  the  types  of 
information  in  their  possession.  These  sources  can  then  be  exhaustively 
tapped  at  a  later  point. 

Another  approach  is  to  start  at  the  top  of  the  organization  and  move 
down  through  the  hierarchy  as  far  as  is  necessary  to  get  an  adequate  story. 
Interviews  at  the  higher  levels  stress  objectives,  program,  the  general  organi- 
zation and  flow  of  work,  external  relationships,  and  supervision.  As  inter- 
viewing proceeds  downward  through  the  agency,  increasing  detail  is  ob- 
tained on  the  distribution  of  work,  the  nature  of  the  activities  being  carried 
on,  the  sequence  of  operations,  and  working  facilities  and  their  use.  This 
system  permits  working  through  channels  and  makes  it  easy  to  locate  each 
successive  piece  of  information  in  its  proper  place  in  the  larger  administra- 
tive setting. 

Interviews  can  also  be  used  to  trace  through  a  procedure  by  asking  each 

24  C/.  Bingham,  Walter  V.  and  Moore,  Bruce  V.,  How  To  Interview,  3d  ed.,  New  York: 
Harper,  1941. 

25  See  Pfiffncr,   Research   Methods  in   Public  Administration,  cit.  above  in  note  21,  p. 


470  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

person  who  successively  participates  in  that  procedure  what  he  does  and 
how,  or  by  retracing  a  specific  completed  action  by  asking  each  person  what 
happened  at  his  point  of  the  operation.  In  the  course  of  interviews,  the 
skilled  analyst  looks  at  working  papers,  observes  the  actual  operations,  and 
brings  into  play  other  aids  to  analysis. 

Obviously,  the  interview  will  not  often  produce  confessions  of  omission 
or  error.  Also,  significant  details  may  be  unintentionally  overlooked  by 
those  furnishing  information.  Certain  administrative  operations  represent- 
ing the  best  or  the  ideal  performance  may  be  confused  with  the  more  typi- 
cal ones.  Spot  experience  may  overshadow  and  distort  customary  day-to-day 
operations.  The  skilled  analyst  must  undertake  to  compensate  for  these 
weaknesses  in  testimony  as  he  recognizes  or  suspects  them. 

Interviews  need  to  be  carefully  scheduled  and  thought  through  in 
advance  if  the  required  information  is  actually  to  be  secured.  A  check 
list  of  points  on  which  information  is  desired  must  be  prepared  and  a  line 
of  questioning  planned  which  will  develop  this  information.  The  inter- 
viewer should  also  be  forearmed  with  knowledge  about  those  he  is  to 
question  so  that  he  will  not  be  in  the  dark  in  devising  his  approach.  The 
success  with  which  the  interview  relationships  are  started  will  have  an  im- 
portant bearing  on  the  fruitfulness  of  subsequent  conversations.  Close  atten- 
tion needs  to  be  given  to  the  atmosphere  engendered  in  the  first  conversation. 

Helpful  hints  to  the  interviewer  would  include  these:  Try  to  see  each 
individual  privately;  encourage  him  to  talk;  be  sympathetic  and  a  good 
listener;  don't  try  to  give  offhand  advice;  make  an  effort  to  get  operators 
to  define  their  problems  and  to  state  what  they  think  should  be  done  about 
them. 

If  the  interview  is  skillfully  handled,  it  will  be  possible  for  the  analyst 
to  win  acceptance  as  one  who  can  help  management  solve  its  problems. 
He  should  also  succeed  in  stimulating  thinking  by  the  operators.  When 
pertinent  to  the  interview,  illustrations  of  principal  forms  and  procedures 
should  be  collected  and  tied  into  the  interview  notes.  The  interview  is 
more  than  an  assembling  of  opinions;  it  is  aimed  at  securing  facts  through 
conversations.  Complete  notes,  including  captions  or  headings  to  facili- 
tate future  references,  should  be  made  after  the  interview  on  the  basis  of  the 
project  outline. 

Observation  of  Operations.  Direct  observation  of  what  is  happening  is 
one  of  the  more  obvious  analysis  tools,  but  unfortunately  one  that  is  too 
often  neglected.  Observation  enables  the  analyst  to  see  operations  in  relation 
to  each  other — a  street-paving  crew  at  work,  or  a  group  of  file  clerks  classi- 
fying, sorting,  storing,  and  pulling  papers.  A  walk  through  an  organization 
with  a  guide  can  be  a  big  reconnaissance  help  in  judging  prima  facie  the 
performance  of  operations,  in  acquiring  an  awareness  of  employee  attitudes 
and  the  cordiality  of  relationships  between  supervisors  and  the  rank  and 
file — in  other  words,  in  getting  the  feel  of  the  place. 


ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT  471 

In  any  survey,  observation  is  essential  to  an  appraisal  of  the  physical 
layout  and  the  use  of  working  tools.  It  is  a  major  element  in  any  motion 
study  in  which  an  individual  operation  is  viewed  again  and  again  to  break 
it  down  into  a  phase  sequence  of  action  or  inaction.  Sometimes  the  motion- 
picture  camera  is  used  so  that  the  operation  can  be  reviewed  repeatedly  in 
slow  motion.  Looking  at  what  is  done  by  each  employee  who  partici- 
pates in  a  procedure  is  one  way  to  trace  the  flow  of  work  through  an  organi- 
zation. Sitting  in  on  staff  conferences  or  meetings  is  another  type  of  direct 
observation — one  in  which  primary  emphasis  is  upon  listening,  rather  than 
upon  looking. 

Understanding  through  observation  becomes  increasingly  difficult  when 
an  individual's  activities  are  diversified  or  variable  or  when  activities  are 
incompletely  reflected  in  actions  or  words.  Looking  or  listening  will  not 
help  when  the  object  of  study  is  a  man  sitting  at  his  desk  formulating 
policy.  Even  though  he  sees  and  hears,  the  skilled  analyst  also  recognizes 
that  in  many  situations  he  may  misunderstand  or  misinterpret  elements 
of  the  transaction  unless  he  uses  other  analytical  tools  as  well. 

Review  of  Communications.  A  great  many  devices  have  been  worked 
out  and  applied  successfully  on  repeated  occasions  in  breaking  down  die 
flow,  distribution,  and  accumulation  of  work.26  One  of  the  best  of  these 
is  the  review  of  working  papers,  either  in  storage  or  as  they  flow  through 
a  distribution  center,  usually  the  mail  room.  Precise,  first-hand  information 
on  the  kinds  of  things  handled,  what  is  done  with  them,  and  the  distribu- 
tion and  flow  of  work  can  facilitate  judgments  on  methods,  organization, 
and  procedure,  and  can  aid  in  figuring  out  what  changes  need  to  be  made. 

It  can  also  be  of  help  in  identifying  the  level  of  difficulty  of  different 
types  of  work.  It  can  reinforce  findings  and  nail  down  recommendations. 
It  can  help  the  analyst  to  avoid  the  overgeneralizations,  misrepresentations, 
or  omissions  that  may  come  from  sole  reliance  on  secondary  sources  or 
personal  interviews.  Working  papers  also  may  be  analyzed  in  order  to 
simplify  communication.  Opportunities  for  form  letters,  check  lists,  and 
other  time-saving  devices  can  be  located  after  such  a  study. 

On  the  other  hand,  reading  files  or  correspondence  can  prove  to  be  an 
inordinately  time-consuming  method  of  administrative  analysis.  For  many 
activities,  moreover,  working  papers  provide  an  inadequate  reflection  of  the 
operation— for  instance,  street  cleaning,  bridge  building,  across-the-counter 
customer  service,  packaging,  filing  operations,  conferences,  and  telephone 
conversations.  Working  papers  may  contain  only  the  end  product  or  other- 
wise fail  to  reflect  fully  what  is  done  and  why. 

Wori^-Load  and  Wor\-Measurement  Data.  The  gathering  and  inter- 
pretation of  statistics  play  an  important  part  in  administrative  analysis,  par- 

26  Reference  may  be  made  to  Glaser,  Comstock,  Administrative  Procedure,  Washington: 
American  Council  on  Public  Affairs,  1941,  offered  as  a  "practical  handbook  for  the  adminis- 
trative analyst";  and  to  Barnes,  Ralph  M.,  Wor^  Methods  Manual,  New  York:  Wiley,  1944. 


472  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

ticularly  in  connection  with  measuring  the  work  passing  through  organiza- 
tion units,  in  evaluating  the  effort  required  to  perform  tasks  in  a  certain 
way,  and  in  arriving  at  a  conclusion  about  the  efficiency  of  operations. 
Work  count,  work  measurement,  and  cost-analysis  techniques  are  all  part  of 
analysis.  By  drawing  together  significant  figures  it  is  possible  to  isolate 
and  identify  administrative  bottlenecks  upon  which  attention  should  be 
concentrated;  point  up  defects  in  the  existing  allocation  of  functions;  reveal 
periodic  peaks  and  valleys  in  work  load  which  can  be  eliminated  by  re- 
scheduling or  by  rearranging  work  assignments;  disclose  unbalance  in  the 
distribution  of  work;  discover  unnecessary  operations;  and  frequently  sup- 
port recommendations  by  a  showing  of  savings  in  time,  money,  or  work 
requirements. 

In  addition,  administrative  results  often  can  be  tested  against  statistically 
developed  standards  of  performance  and  accomplishment.  Many  functions 
of  municipal  government  have  been  closely  related  to  standards  of  cost 
accounting  or  work  measurement.  Less  has  been  done  at  the  federal  level 
that  is  worthy  of  the  name  of  cost  accounting  or  work  measurement.  Inter- 
est is  developing,  however,  particularly  in  the  area  of  administrative  services. 

Charting  Devices.  Much  help  is  available  to  the  analyst  in  the  various 
kinds  of  charts,  pictures,  and  diagrams  that  have  been  developed  to  facilitate 
the  clear  recording  of  data  and  to  speed  up  the  process  of  communicating 
ideas.27  To  show  a  succession  of  operations,  a  wide  variety  of  charting 
devices  has  been  evolved. 

The  organization  chart  is  commonly  used  to  show  the  basic  allocation 
of  functions,  the  hierarchy  of  responsibilities,  and  at  times  the  number  and 
classes  of  employees  performing  each  main  function.  The  work-distribu- 
tion chart  pictures  detailed  individual  work  assignments  of  the  first-line 
operating  unit.  There  is  the  work-flow  chart,  portraying  the  general  se- 
quence of  major  activities  through  the  organization.  The  process  chart 
gives  a  picture  of  the  detailed,  consecutive,  individual  operations,  trans- 
portations, storages,  delays,  and  inspections  by  which  a  job  is  done.  The 
right-and-left-hand  chart  or  the  simo-motion  chart  can  be  used  when  a 
breakdown  of  the  work  movements  of  one  individual  is  in  order. 

In  analyzing  working  arrangements  and  the  utility  and  layout  of  facili- 
ties, pictorial  diagrams  can  vividly  present  the  individual  or  group  operation. 
Space  analysis  becomes  much  easier  with  a  layout  diagram.  Lines  showing 
the  flow  of  work  or  the  number  and  types  of  personal  contacts  in  a 
given  time  period  can  clearly  reflect  possible  defects  in  existing  physical 
arrangements. 

Reports.  Throughout  the  course  of  analysis,  facts  are  mentally  organized 

27  An  excellent  presentation  is  to  be  found  in  Finley,  Harold  A.,  "Principles  and  Methods 
of  Work  Simplification,"  in  Proceedings  of  the  Life  Office  Management  Association,  p.  227  ff. 
Neiv  York,  1943.  See  also  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Management  Bulletin  on 
Process  Charting,  Nov.,  1945. 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  473 

and  related  to  one  other,  to  past  experience,  and  to  previously  accumulated 
knowledge.  In  any  substantial  fact-gathering,  however,  some  systematic 
recording  of  data  is  necessary.  This  is  done  to  facilitate  either  the  develop- 
ment of  findings  and  recommendations  or  the  communication  of  ideas. 

Data  must  be  organized  to  fit  the  audience  if  recommendations  are  to 
be  accepted  or  effected^  Will  the  top  executive  or  line  operator  absorb  and 
understand  proposals  most  easily  through  conversation,  charts,  pictures, 
a  brief  written  summary,  or  a  lengthy  report?  Does  he  like  to  get  right 
down  to  proposed  changes  or  does  he  prefer  first  to  think  through  the  facts 
or  consider  the  existing  defects?  What  subjects  or  ideas  attract  or  repel 
those  who  must  decide  upon  or  put  into  effect  survey  recommendations? 
The  answers  to  these  questions  should  control  the  organization  of  report 
materials. 

In  addition,  questions  of  timing  will  have  a  bearing  on  the  way  in  which 
the  materials  are  brought  together.  Should  conclusions  and  recommenda- 
tions be  presented  as  they  are  developed,  and  agreements  be  reached  stage 
by  stage,  or  should  the  story  be  presented  as  a  whole  at  the  end  of  the 
project?  If  the  latter,  should  the  report  be  offered  as  a  finished  product 
or  should  there  be  submission  of  a  tentative  report  subject  to  revision  after 
discussion  ?  Whatever  the  decision  on  tactics,  it  is  highly  desirable  to  obtain 
agreement  on  findings  before  presenting  conclusions,  and  on  premises  and 
conclusions  before  presenting  recommendations. 

In  submitting  the  report,  plans  need  to  be  thought  out  for  the  imple- 
mentation of  the  proposals.  This  may  require  establishing  a  special  unit 
within  the  organization  surveyed  to  carry  forward  the  recommendations; 
or  seeing  to  it  that  special  staff  is  employed  to  do  the  job;  or  temporarily 
transferring  some  of  the  analysts  who  did  the  study  to  the  agency  or  unit 
studied.  Continued  participation  by  the  study  group  may  be  required  to 
install  new  devices  or  methods;  to  work  initially  with  the  agency  or  unit; 
to  prepare  action  documents  for  effecting  changes;  to  revise  procedures; 
or  to  take  over  an  operation  temporarily  as  a  demonstration.  Whenever  pos- 
sible, it  is  desirable  so  to  arrange  matters  that  the  proposals  will  be  adopted 
by  the  line  operator  as  his  own.  Maximum  effect  cannot  be  derived  as  long 
as  the  product  remains  that  of  an  outsider. 

4.  BASIC  RESOURCES  IN  MANAGEMENT  IMPROVEMENT 

Qualifications  for  Analysis.  Three  types  of  abilities  and  backgrounds  are 
important  in  the  formulation  oFsound  administrative  proposals.  The  first  is 
an  understanding  of  administration.  The  more  an  individual  knows  about 
public  administration  and  the  more  experience  he  has  had  in  dealing  with  or- 
ganization and  method  problems,  the  better  fitted  he  is  to  analyze  a  new 
problem.  He  knows  the  kinds  of  things  that  give  trouble,  the  points  of 
friction,  the  bottlenecks,  the  telltale  evidences  of  an  effectively  or  ineffectively 
operating  organization,  and  the  arrangements  that  generally  work  out  well. 


474  ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

Skill  in  the  actual  process  of  observation  and  analysis  is  the  second  essen- 
tial. "This  is  partly  an  innate  ability  and  partly  a  matter  of  training  and 
^experience.  If  one  is  schooled  to  look  for  possible  improvements  and  is 
trained  in  analytical  methods,  he  can  quickly  broaden  the  value  of  his 
observations  and  expedite  his  gathering  and  assimilation  of  the  facts. 

THiethird  personal  characteristic  required  in  the  development  of  more 
effective  organization  and  mcthodsis  judgment.  The  individual  must  be 
objective  in  his  view  of  lif e"around  Him  or  of  the  particular  situation  with 
which  he  is  dealing.  He  must  have  the  ability  to  see  both  the  forest  and  the 
trees.  He  must  also  have  a  flair  for  developing  practical  solutions  and  get- 
ting them  across.  This  involves  a  great  deal  of  human  understanding  and 
instinctive  behavior  if  situations  are  to  be  interpreted  accurately. 

5^/77  in  Human  Relations.  Underlying  all  such  personal  requirements 
is  the  need  for  skill  in  human  relations.  The  analyst  is  constantly  searching 
for  operating  arrangements  in  which  individuals  are  able  to  act  more  easily 
and  effectively.  It  may  even  be  said  that  administrative  analysis  is,  in  large 
part,  psychological  analysis. 

Psychological  factors  enter  into  the  survey  process  all  along  the  line. 
Fact-gathering  involves  face-to-face  contacts.  There  must  be  cultivation  of 
good  relations  to  build  up  useful  sources  of  information  and  ideas.  The  pro- 
ductivity of  interviews  will  depend  to  a  degree  upon  how  well  one  re- 
sponds to  the  reactions  and  attitudes  of  the  individuals  interviewed.  Dis- 
cussion of  ideas  or  proposals  couched  in  the  language  in  which  an  individual 
thinks  and  feels  may  transform  his  opposition  or  indifference  into  coopera- 
tion or,  at  least,  receptivity.  This  is  particularly  important  in  dealing  with 
administrators  and  supervisors  who  must  pass  upon  or  apply  the  recom- 
mendations developed.  Finally,  recommendations  may  have  to  be  made  in 
the  light  of  major  personality  factors  in  the  organization. 

The  competent  top  administrator,  the  supervisors  at  the  various  levels 
in  the  hierarchy,  and  the  administrative  general-staff  personnel  are  all  in 
need  of  these  abilities.  The  latter — the  administrative  assistant,  the  budget 
officer,  or  the  administrative-planning  officer — will  find  competence  in  ad- 
ministrative analysis  their  principal  stock-in-trade.  Their  whole  day  is 
devoted  to  observing,  diagnosing,  evaluating,  stimulating,  and  recommend- 
ing. As  they  become  masters  of  the  techniques,  they  will  be  able  effec- 
tively to  accomplish  in  a  week — and  perhaps  in  a  more  thoroughgoing 
fashion — what  would  take  the  unskilled  analyst  months. 

The  top  administrator  has  insufficient  time  to  analyze  many  problems. 
However,  he  will  need  to  know  of  the  existence  of  the  various  methods  of 
identifying  and  overcoming  difficulties.  He  will  also  want  to  be  assured 
that  the  recommendations  or  the  alternative  choices  submitted  to  him  are 
the  product  of  effective  analysis.  The  able  executive  will  bear  these  findings 
in  mind  in  virtually  everything  he  does. 

Analysis  also  occurs  as  the  administrator,  with  or  without  special  staff 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  475 

assistance,  reviews  the  papers  that  pass  over  his  desk  and  observes  the  or- 
ganization's end  product.  The  same  is  true  of  the  rank  and  file  of  super- 
visors. The  lower  the  level,  the  more  can  the  supervisor  see  at  first-hand 
the  detail  problems  that  confront  the  organization  and  the  better  is  his  posi- 
tion to  figure  out  solutions.  But  human  beings  function  largely  by  habit; 
they  get  used  to  their  surroundings  and  their  established  routine.28  The 
supervisor  who  is  constantly  challenging  his  own  methods  of  work  and 
keeping  on  the  lookout  for  better  ways  of  doing  it  will  be  able  to  solve  a 
mass  of  problems  which  the  dull-eyed  supervisor  will  never  see. 

Training  Surveys.  The  methods  of  fact-finding  or  of  surveying  are  fre- 
quently thought  to  be  restricted  to  so-called  experts  and  top  administrative 
staffs.  However,  during  World  War  II,  fact-finding  techniques  were  com- 
bined with  training  techniques  in  developing  in  first-line  supervisors  the 
skills  necessary  to  carry  out  their  portion  of  the  total  management  job. 
Two  outstanding  examples  specifically  fit  into  our  context. 

One  is  the  "J"  programs  discussed  in  the  preceding  chapter.20  These 
programs  were  worked  out  with  one  primary  aim  in  mind — to  supply  war 
industry  rapidly  with  foremen  in  sufficient  numbers  and  with  sufficient 
ability  to  meet  industrial  expansion  and  increased  production  requirements. 
In  using  the  "J"  programs  for  purposes  other  than  those  for  which  they 
were  designed,  careful  review  should  be  made  of  both  the  individual  pro- 
gram and  the  situation  to  which  it  is  to  be  applied,  so  that  any  necessary 
adaptations  may  be  made. 

The  second  illustration  is  the  work-simplification  program,  also  pre- 
viously discussed.30  Work  simplification  has  long  been  practiced  by  special- 
ists. During  World  War  II  Lt.  Col.  John  A.  Aldridge  of  the  Quartermaster 
Corps  Control  Division,  Army  Service  Forces,  developed  office-work  sim- 
plification principally  in  terms  of  process  charting  and  layout-flow  charting. 
He  did  an  outstanding  job  in  introducing  the  gang-process  chart  as  a  device 
for  analyzing  material-handling  problems.  Basing  its  efforts  on  mass  em- 
ployee participation,  the  Quartermaster  Corps  saved  26.4  per  cent  of  all 
manpower  covered  by  the  program  for  other  assignments  in  the  expanding 
war  effort.  The  United  States  Bureau  of  the  Budget  added  to  the  analysis 
technique  of  the  process  chart  the  techniques  of  the  work-distribution  chart 
and  the  work  count,  and  packaged  them  in  such  a  manner  that  busy  first- 
line  supervisors  could  be  instructed  in  the  use  of  these  elementary  devices 
in  a  few  short  sessions.  In  the  Office  of  Price  Administration,  savings  of 
nearly  $2  millions  were  reported  after  a  concentrated  effort  on  the  basis  of 
the  bureau's  program. 

Work  simplification  requires  for  its  most  beneficial  use  an  interested 

28  Cf.  above  Ch.  17,  "Government  by  Procedure,"  sec.  1,  "The  Nature  and  Limitations  of 
Procedure." 

29  See  above  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec.  2,  "The  Supervisory  Skills." 

bid.  and  above  Ch.  17,  "Government  by  Procedure,"  sec.  4,  "Creadon  and  Criteria.1 


476  ADMINISTRATIVE   SELF-IMPROVEMENT 

middle  management  and  a  competent  expert  or  small  staff  of  experts  in 
administrative  analysis  to  cope  with  problems  supervisors  turn  up  which 
ire  beyond  the  scope  of  their  authority.  The  bureau's  work-simplification 
training  program,  including  the  visual  aids  used,  has  been  published  by  the 
Public  Administration  Service.31 

Employee-Initiated  Action.  Administrative  and  training  surveys  are 
initiated  by  top  management,  and  even  work-simplification  programs  focus 
only  on  the  first-line  supervisor.  What  of  the  rank  and  file?  Employee-sug- 
gestion systems  have  been  instituted  in  many  governmental  units  to  bring 
about  management  improvements.32  Employees  are  provided  with  forms  on 
which  they  outline  a  proposed  improvement,  such  as  a  simplified  proce- 
dure, a  new  piece  of  equipment,  a  scheme  for  saving  effort,  or  some  better 
type  of  operation  control.  Sometimes  financial  awards  are  given;  in  other 
cases,  reliance  has  been  upon  public  citation.  In  the  War  Department, 
10  per  cent  of  the  employees  have  participated  each  year  in  this  scheme. 
From  June,  1943,  to  December,  1944,  cash  awards  of  $653,762  were  paid; 
189,711  suggestions  had  come  forth  in  this  period.  Annual  savings  from 
them  were  estimated  at  $54,930,931.  In  the  Navy  Department,  savings 
resulting  from  employee  suggestions  were  estimated  at  $15  millions  a  year. 

The  significance  of  employee-initiated  action  is  not  limited  to  cash 
savings.  It  rests  also  in  th^  highly  intangible  but 


improved  employee  morale.  As  each  employee  thinks  of  job  processes  on 
his  own  initiative,  he  tends  to  take  greater  interest  in  his  job  and  to  become 
more  closely  affiliated  with  the  organization.  This  feeling  is  increased 
materially  as  employees  are  permitted  to  share  in  management  discussions. 
Shop  committees  and  labor-management  committees  composed  of  supervis- 
ors and  employees  have  brought  about  better  common  understanding  of 
problems  arising  on  either  side.  Depending  upon  the  underlying  interest 
of  management,  they  have  contributed  to  effective  settlement  of  many 
administrative  issues. 

Summary.  In  the  last  ten  years,  interest  in  better  administration  by 
responsible  public  officials  and  large  numbers  of  rank-and-file  government 
employees  has  multipled.  This  interest  has  taken  the  form  of  intelligent 
analysis  of  administrative  problems,  to  the  end  that  day-to-day  programs 
are  carried  on  more  effectively  and  efficiently.  Marked  increase  is  noticeable 
iiythe  development  and  use  of  sound  techniques  of  analysis. 

/  Programs  of  administrative  improvement  have  literally  spread  like 
wildfire  on  the  municipal,  state,  and  federal  levels  of  government.  There 
is  danger  during  an  expansion  of  this  scope  that  techniques  may  be  applied 
to  situations  which  actually  do  not  fit  the  conditions.  This  is  due  to  an  un- 
derstandable eagerness  to  try  something  that  has  proved  successful  else- 

»!  Publication  No.  91,  Chicago,  1945. 

82  C/.  also  above  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec.  4,  "Supervision  and  Employee 
Initiative." 


ADMINISTRATIVE  SELF-IMPROVEMENT  477 

where.  Innovation  for  innovation's  sake  should  be  guarded  against.  Tech-, 
niques  should  be  adapted  to  specific  situations.  Only  through  experience 
tested  inmaaiiqld  ways^^-Wc-gauT  useful  generalizations. 

5e~continuing  growth  of  interest  in  management  improvement  gener- 
ally must  be  based  on  a  firm  foundation  of  testing  results  and  interchange 
of  information.  However,  much  remains  still  to  be  done  in  both  these  areas. 
The  attempt  to  make  available  to  first-line  supervisors  and  employees  knowl- 
edge of  the  techniques  of  analysis,  and  to  open  further  avenues  of  wider 
participation  in  management  should  be  fostered  vigorously  in  order  to  se- 
cure closer  communication  of  ideas  between  supervisors  and  subordinates 
throughout  the  entire  administrative  structure. 


CHAPTER 


Morale  and  Discipline 

1.   THE  MEANING  OF  MORALE 

Components  of  Morale.  Leonard  D.  White  has  said :  "Morale  is  both  an 
index  of  a  sound  employment  situation  and  a  positive  means  of  building  an 
efficient  organization.  It  reflects  a  social-psychological  situation,  a  state  of 
mind  in  which  men  and  women  voluntarily  seek  to  develop  and  apply  their 
full  powers  to  the  task  upon  which  they  are  engaged,  by  reason  of  the  intel- 
lectual or  moral  satisfaction  which  they  derive  from  their  own  self-realiza- 
tion,  their  achievements  in  their  chosen  field,  and  their  pride  in  the  service."1 

Thus  considered,  morale  is  obviously  the  very  essence  of  successful  ad- 
ministration. Whether  the  undertaking  administered  be  an  army,  a  public 
agency,  or  a  private  enterprise,  it  is  clear  that  if  its  leaders  aspire  to  sustained 
accomplishment  of  defined  results,  they  must  master  the  problem  of  morale 
both  as  a  standard  of  appraising  the  effectiveness  of  their  organization  and 
as  a  technique  of  maximizing  its  esprit  de  corps. 

In  the  past  decade,  the  elements  of  morale  have  been  the  subject  of  ex- 
tensive exploration  by  both  students  and  practitioners  of  administration.2 

1  White,  Leonard  D.,  "Administration,  Public,"  Encyclopedia  of  the  Social  Sciences,  Vol. 
I,  p.  446,  New  York:  Macmiilan,  1930. 

2  For  a  cross  section  of  the  best  scholarship  available  on  the  subject  of  this  chapter,  see 
Tead,  Ordway,  Human  Nature  and  Management,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,   1933,  and  The 
Art  of  Leadership,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1935;  Follett,  Mary  P.,  Dynamic  Administration, 
cd.  by  Metcalf,  Henry  C.  and  Urwick,  Lyndall,  New  York:  Harper,  1942;  Urwick,  Lyndall  and 
Brech,    E.    F.    L.,    Thirteen    Pioneers,   p.    48    ff.,   London:    Management   Publications,    1945; 
Roethlisberger,  Fritz  J.,  Management  and  Morale,  Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press,  1941; 
Roethlisberger,  Fritz  J.  and  Dick  son,  William  J.,  Management  and  the  Worker,  Cambridge: 
Harvard  University  Press,  1943;  Mayo,  Elton,  The  Social  Problems  of  an  Industrial  Civilization, 
Boston:   Harvard   School   of   Business  Administration,    1945;  Pearson,  John,   "Teamwork,"   in 
Morstein  Marx,   Fritz,  ed.,  Public  Management  in  the  New  Democracy,  ch.  6,  New  York: 
Harper,  1940;  Graduate  School  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture,  Administra- 
tive Management:  Principles  and  Techniques,  Lancaster:  Lancaster  Press,  1938;  Viteles,  Morris 
S.,  Industrial  Psychology,  New  York:  Norton,  1932;  Niles,  Mary  C.  H.,  Middle  Management, 
New   York:   Harper,   1941;   Mosher,   William   E.   and   Kingsley,   J.  Donald,  Public  Personnel 
Administration,  rev.  ed.,   New  York:   Harper,    1941;  Tcad,  Ordway  and  Metcalf,  Henry  C., 
Personnel  Administration,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1933;  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  The  Execu- 
tive in  Action,  New  York:  Harper,  1945. 

478 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  479 

Identification  of  the  components  of  morale,  however,  is  still  elusive  despite 
common  agreement  upon  several  generalizations.  These  generalizations  are 
at  least  useful  terms  of  exposition.  One  is  that  the  group  climate  must  pro- 
vide opportunity  for  individual  self-expression  by  the  members  of  the  group. 
Another  is  that  the  cooperative  context  must  furnish  outlets  for  the  individ- 
ual's pride  in  his  own  workmanship.  Still  another  is  that  members  of  the 
group  must  accept  the  purposes  and  values  of  the  group  as  their  own — that 
they  have  a  sense  of  belonging  to  the  group  or  of  identity  with  it.  These 
may  be  described  as  the  individualistic  bases  of  morale. 

Of  equal  importance  are  those  bases  from  which  the  group  derives  its 
own  collective  individuality  and  vitality.  In  many  ways,  the  first  among 
them  is  personal  opportunity  for  creative  participation  in  the  formulation 
and  pursuit  of  widely  shared  group  objectives.  Not  only  is  it  important 
thus  to  weld  the  individual  member  and  the  group  together;  it  is  also  im- 
perative that  the  group  conceives  of  itself  as  serving  the  ends  and  goals 
of  the  larger  community. 

The  highest  morale  has  an  intellectual  as  well  as  an  emotional  quality. 
Its  intellectual  quality  results  from  emphasis  upon  information,  understand- 
ing, and  intercommunication,  which  rest  in  turn  on  genuine  participation 
in  institutional  thinking,  planning,  deciding,  and  evaluating.  These  are  the 
dynamics  of  morale.  Some  observers  have  laid  great  stress  on  a  more  static 
component — that  of  the  security  of  the  individual  within  the  group.  Secur- 
ity, however,  is  more  accurately  a  by-product,  not  a  creator  of  group  morale. 
Its  overemphasis  inevitably  adulterates  morale. 

Not  a  few  students  have  concluded  that  there  are  certain  additional  re- 
quirements for  the  maintenance  of  positive  morale.  They  underscore  the 
need  for  homogeneity  in  the  purposes  of  the  group.  There  must  be,  they 
say,  at  least  the  absence  of  inconsistency  in  group  purposes,  since  contradic- 
tions produce  stresses  and  strains  destructive  of  group  identity.  To  be  sure, 
heterogeneity  of  purpose  which  engenders  within  the  group  a  conscious  and 
prolonged  competition  in  the  pursuit  of  irreconcilable  objectives  is  hostile  to 
morale.  Yet  the  limits  of  tolerance  may  be  fairly  generous.  The  group 
thrives  upon  variety  in  points  of  view  as  well  as  upon  unity.  Of  course,  gen- 
eral agreement  upon  the  master  objective  is  necessary.  However,  construc- 
tive competition  as  to  means,  particularly  as  to  those  means  which  call  for 
adaptation  to  time  and  circumstance,  is  a  generator  of  morale — not  its 

enemy. 

Homogeneity  in  the  composition  of  the  group,  it  is  argued,  is  also  es- 
sential. Staff  homogeneity  with  respect  to  age,  ability,  energy,  and  perma- 
nence is  deceptively  attractive,  but  it  also  may  cause  undue  narrowness.  The 
search  should  rather  be  for  that  fine  balance  of  staff  composition  which 
gives  to  the  group  the  efficiency  which  comes  from  maturity  and  the 
momentum  which  comes  from  youth. 

Other  writers  have  suggested  that  the  group  must  have  a  conviction  ol 


480  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

success— that  is,  accomplishments  must  stand  out  in  terms  of  group  purposes 
and  be  obvious  to  outside  observers  as  well  as  to  the  group  itself.  Such  con* 
ditions  are  usually  beyond  the  control  of  the  group,  however.  There  is  only 
a  relatively  brief  time-span  during  which  the  group  may  be  sustained  by 
the  near  prospect  of  success  or,  in  some  rare  instances,  by  the  knowledge 
that  the  goal  is  distant  but  worth  striving  for. 

Still  other  students  have  contended  that  morale  depends  upon  the  degree 
of  successful  and  enduring  indoctrination  which  the  group  receives.  The 
validity  of  this  contention  is  limited  by  the  boundary  between  education 
and  demagogy.  Indoctrination  is  an  instrument,  the  utility  of  which  is 
linked  to  its  educative  quality  and  the  soundness  of  its  premises.  Indoctrina- 
tion is  one  thing,  the  character  of  the  doctrine  is  another. 

True  Coin  and  Counterfeit.  Morale  is  frequently  confused  with  its  coun- 
terfeits. The  crowd  has  its  moments  of  evanescent  enthusiasm.  The  clan  has 
its  solid,  introverted  self-sufficiency.  The  clique  has  its  conspiratorial  intoxi- 
cation. The  caste,  conscious  of  its  exclusive  membership,  has  its  somber, 
pretentious  symbols  of  unity.  The  gang  has  its  exaggerated  forms  of  self- 
importance. 

These  are  not  manifestations  of  morale  in  any  meaningful  sense.  Morale 
is  a  significant  term  to  those  concerned  with  administration  only  when  the 
concept  has  progressive  social  utility.  To  serve  a  progressive  function  in 
administration,  morale  must  be  stripped  of  its  parochial  values.  It  cannot 
have  emotionally  or  intellectually  neutral  tones.  In  the  administrative  en- 
vironment, the  significance  of  morale  lies:  first,  in  its  barometric  function — 
its  function  as  a  psychological  index  of  the  net  quality  of  management;  and, 
second,  in  its  instrumental  function — its  contribution  of  emphasis  and 
method  to  the  values  of  creative  group  effort. 

In  this  perspective,  group  morale  involves  balance,  flexibility,  maturity, 
continuity,  persistence  against  adversity,  and  capacity  for  constant  renewal. 
Balance  and  maturity  are  the  product  of  a  total  perspective  of  the  group — 
its  raison  d'etre,  its  objectives  and  goals,  its  concept  of  itself.  Pursued  too 
deliberately,  balance  and  maturity  become  superannuation.  The  group  per- 
spective becomes  a  system  of  static  stereotypes,  empty  symbols  of  a  dead  past. 
Continuity  in  morale  is  still  more  fugitive,  for  morale  is  always  less  difficult 
to  evoke  than  to  sustain.  Morale,  as  the  spirit  of  the  group,  is  a  living  thing. 
To  be  sustained,  it  must  be  constantly  renewed  by  the  vitality  of  day-to-day 
relationships  and  operations. 

Persistence  against  adversity  is  easily  produced  upon  occasion,  but  its 
continuance  is  rarely  encountered  except  in  the  counterfeit  form  of  resist- 
ance to  change.  Nothing  is  so  fatally  easy  to  develop  as  rigid  habit.  It 
represents  ease,  familiarity,  certainty,  "security."  These,  however,  are  the 
attractive  forms  of  false  morale. 

Morale  is  flexible.  Flexibility  and  persistence  of  morale  require  the  high- 
est, level  of  leadership.  Such  leadership  brings  forth  constant  participation 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  481 

in  the  sharing  of  aims  and  plans,  in  judgment  and  evaluation,  in  adapta- 
tion to  changed  circumstances.  The  group  learns  much  more  readily  the 
opposite  habits:  smugness,  complacency,  exclusiveness,  attachment  to  some 
plateau  of  morale,  rationalization  of  limited  accomplishment,  acceptance  of 
the  present  unattainability  of  some  peak  that  has  been  reached  in  its  past. 
It  is  always  tempted  by  the  familiarity,  comfort,  and  ease  of  old  ways— the 
dead  level  of  mediocrity. 

Democratic  Implications  of  Morale.  These  generalizations  about  the 
nature  of  morale  march  clearly  toward  one  major  conclusion.  Morale  is 
a  democratic  concept.  Fascism,  Nazism,  and  Shintoism  may  have  seemed 
very  effective  "morale"  builders.  However,  theirs  was  a  brittle  "morale,"  an 
unyielding  spirit  which  when  cracked  was  shattered.  As  circumstances 
shifted,  their  rigidity  of  habit  and  attitude  was  unable  to  adapt. 

The  product  of  indoctrination  and  repetition,  this  type  of  "morale" 
lacked  understanding.  A  response  to  authority,  it  lacked  initiative,  inven- 
tiveness, and  imagination.  An  intelligent  and  simultaneously  persistent 
morale  in  a  complex,  changing  world  must  be  democratic.  It  must  enlist 
voluntary  and  creative  participation  of  each  member  of  the  group  in  the 
formation  of  group  purposes  and  the  attainment  of  group  goals. 

The  essence  of  democratic  morale  is  to  be  found  in  its  accent  on 
common  knowledge,  initiative,  resourcefulness,  and  imagination  throughout 
the  group.  Democratic  morale  is  built  upon  the  free  and  constructive  sharing 
by  all  members  of  the  group  in  the  definition  and  accomplishment  of  the 
group's  purposes.  It  seeks  to  evoke  this  participation  through  the  art  of 
leadership,  not  by  authority;  through  the  inner  unity  of  the  group,  not  by 
its  division  into  hierarchical  levels;  through  the  dynamic  drive  of  the  whole 
group,  not  by  requirements  imposed  by  command.  The  literature  of  morale 
probes  into  the  wellsprings  of  human  motivation  and  response.  Its  findings 
are  decisive  in  the  endorsement  of  democratic  premises,  conclusive  in  the 
indictment  o^  the  uses  of  self-centered  authority  and  the  ephemeral  effects 
of  involuntary  participation. 

Doctrinal  Counter  influences.  There  is  still  great  need  in  the  public  serv- 
ice for  the  development  of  an  understanding  of  morale  in  its  most  positive 
forms.  We  have  depended  too  long  upon  the  lawyer  and  the  engineer  tc 
provide  the  master  theory  of  human  relations  in  public  administration.  As 
the  main  if  unacknowledged  craftsmen  of  administrative  doctrine,  the) 
have  labored  mightily  to  repair  the  defaults  of  others,  but  they  have  not  beer 
equipped  to  do  the  complete  job.  The  concepts  brought  forth  in  both 
quarters  have  been  equally  congenial,  equally  plausible,  and  equally  false 
What  they  have  produced  is  not  a  democratic  theory  of  administration 
however  much  their  literary  efforts  have  been  sweetened  with  the  strategic 
use  of  such  words  as  "American"  and  "democratic."  Fundamentally,  theii 
product  has  tended  toward  authoritarian  dogma. 

The  proof  is  the  doxology  implicit  in  contemporary  theory  of  publi< 


482  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

administration.  Its  most  ancient  and  revered  precept  is  that  the  state  is 
sovereign.  It  follows  that  not  only  are  those  who  live  within  the  state's 
boundaries  inhibited  by  the  near-divinity  of  rigid  forms,  but  also  and  espe- 
cially that  those  who  work  for  the  state  are  required  to  respect  its  sov- 
ereignty. The  influence  of  this  concept  is  universal  and  subtle  on  all  the 
premises  employed  by  the  architects  of  administrative  doctrine.  The  con- 
cept of  internal  sovereignty  has  provided  the  alchemy  by  which  the  author- 
ity and  the  unilateral  prestige  of  the  abstract  state  has  been  transferred  to  all 
those  who  command  the  enterprises  of  government. 

The  lawyer  is  prone  to  construct  an  administrative  universe  out  of  a 
logic  concerned  with  the  right  ordering  of  words  on  paper,  a  process  to 
which  human  behavior  and  human  motivation  seem  irrelevant.  The 
engineer  looks  to  the  efficient  manipulation  of  materials — blocks  of  stone, 
bars  of  steel,  and  the  more  mysterious  action  and  reaction  of  molecule  and 
atom,  light  and  sound.  Human  behavior  may  appear  to  him  as  an  equilib- 
rium of  forces.  He  is  apt  to  forget  that  in  administration  these  forces  are 
animate  and  impulsive.  To  both  the  lawyer  as  an  artisan  of  words  and  the 
engineer  as  a  manipulator  of  materials,  authoritarian  concepts  of  administra- 
tion have  seemed  necessary  and  virtuous.  Each  has  found  the  tradition  and 
the  myth  of  the  sovereign  state  convincing  as  an  article  of  faith  and  con- 
venient as  an  instrument  of  command. 

No  less  influential  has  been  their  elaboration  of  hierarchy  as  indispen- 
sable and  immutable.  Hierarchy  is  seen  by  them  as  the  alternative  to 
disorder.  The  natural  place  of  hierarchy  as  one  of  the  methods  of  group 
action  has  been  exalted  to  a  higher  status — that  of  the  central  instrument  of 
organization  to  which  all  other  means  are  subordinate.  This  elaboration 
has  obscured  the  fact  that,  whatever  its  convenient  and  proper  uses,  hierarchy 
may  operate  as  a  negation  of  democracy  and  as  an  adulterant  of  morale. 

In  the  theory  of  public  administration,  the  derivatives  of  hierarchy  take 
many  forms.  One  of  the  most  universal  is  the  organization  chart,  used  to 
produce  that  illusion  of  symmetry  and  finality  which  seems  to  give  the 
lawyer  and  the  engineer  great  emotional  satisfaction.  But  the  organization 
chart  alone,  whether  made  manifest  in  visual  or  verbal  form,  fails  to  pro- 
vide a  sufficient  cloak  for  the  needs  of  authority.  Consequently,  there  is 
the  enshrinement  of  the  written  procedure  and  the  directive.  These,  how- 
ever necessary  they  may  be  as  pragmatic  means,  may  also  be  used  to  spell 
out  in  persuasive  and  impressive  ritual  the  abstract  implications  of  hier- 
archy and  the  inarticulate  lesson  of  the  organization  chart. 

The  language  of  the  chart  is  usually  the  language  of  authority  and  com- 
mand, rarely  the  language  of  leadership  and  collaboration.  "Span  of  control," 
"chain  of  command,"  "final  authority"—-these  are  familiar  figures  of  thought. 
The  political  scientist  and  the  student  of  public  administration — not  yet 
entirely  free  from  intellectual  subordination  to  the  lawyer  and  the  engineer 
—have  added  still  other  verses  to  the  authoritarian  doxology.  Their  devo- 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  483 

tion  to  the  concept  of  hierarchy  has  been  expressed  in  the  creation  of 
additional  pillars  of  authority— notably  the  staff  office  as  a  device  of  control 
to  police  the  organization  and  to  guard  its  procedural  supports. 

Impact  of  Military  and  Business  Prototypes.  Other  and  powerful  in- 
fluences have  abetted  the  growth  of  authoritarian  administrative  theory. 
Prominent  among  these  has  been  the  imitation  of  military  administration, 
reflected  most  clearly  in  the  structure  and  habits  of  agencies  concerned  with 
public  safety.  In  these  enterprises  appear,  in  most  complete  form,  the 
trappings  of  command  represented  by  the  varied  insignia  of  grades  of  author- 
ity. Moreover,  the  military  tradition  exerts  its  influence  in  many  other 
administrative  areas  in  more  subtle  ways. 

Even  more  pervasive  and  influential  in  public  administration  has  been 
the  example  of  private  enterprise.  Here  the  concepts,  forms,  and  usages 
of  authoritarian  management  have  been  less  softened  by  the  impact  of  demo- 
cratic pressures.  In  this  area  of  human  effort,  authority  and  hierarchy  pay 
more  immediate  dividends.  In  fact,  so  conclusive  have  been  the  dividends 
that  few  theoretical  concessions  have  been  made,  and  in  even  fewer  in- 
stances has  practice  bowed  to  democratic  premises.  The  literature  of  private 
management,  indeed,  shows  very  few  of  the  doubts  of  hierarchy  and  the 
marks  of  democratic  aspiration  now  found  in  some  of  the  writings  on 
public  administration.  Despite  this  fact,  most  of  the  pleas  for  ratification 
of  new  methods  in  public  administration  still  seek  the  endorsement  of 
private-enterprise  analogy.  Applied  without  reference  to  social  values  of 
public  service,  the  dogmas  of  efficiency  and  economy,  for  example,  are  un- 
democratic. Yet  they  are  consistently  invoked  by  the  theorist  and  prac- 
titioner of  public  administration  as  the  main  rationalization,  or  at  least  the 
protective  coloration,  for  almost  every  formula  of  improvement. 

These  are  the  principal  but  not  the  only  barriers  to  the  development  of 
a  fruitful  theory  and  a  productive  methodology  for  the  stimulation  of 
morale  in  the  public  service.  The  task  is  no  less  than  the  rediscovery  of  the 
basic  assumptions  upon  which  the  democratic  experiment  began,  and  their 
laborious  application  to  the  habits  of  management  in  all  our  public  enter- 
prises. Its  difficulty  lies  not  only  in  the  birth-pains  of  new  concepts  but 
even  more  in  the  repudiation  of  the  seductive  nostrums  of  authority.  For 
the  latter  have  acquired  the  benediction  of  "common  sense"  and  common 
prejudice. 

2.  BUILDING  GROUP  MORALE 

Basic  Premises.  We  frequently  forget  that  democracy  is  a  comparatively 
new  and  a  still  timidly  applied  concept.  In  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth 
centuries  it  meant  primarily  the  rule  of  the  majority.  It  was  associated 
with  the  political  and  legal  forms  of  the  ballot,  a  representative  legislature, 
a  written  constitution,  and  a  bill  of  rights.  These  institutional  develop- 
ments were  the  more  obvious  expressions  of  deeper  changes  in  other  aspects 


484  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

of  life.  Among  them  were  the  collapse  of  feudalism,  the  rise  of  industry 
and  trade,  and  the  establishment  of  a  free  market.  The  entire  transforma- 
tion had  the  effect  of  dissolving  the  bonds  of  tyranny  and  opening  the 
channels  of  initiation  and  invention  to  large  groups  that  were  hitherto 
bound  by  authoritarian  controls.  The  enormous  growth  of  America  was 
due  largely  to  the  existence  of  conditions  which  released  the  innovative 
spirit  in  so  many  of  our  people. 

Yet  the  ideas,  attitudes,  and  customs  of  authority  persist.  Orthodox  doc- 
trine of  military  organization  and  discipline  still  reflects  a  command  system. 
Administration  in  industry,  government,  and  education  continues  to  lean 
heavily  upon  formal  authority.  Thus,  as  our  life  has  become  more  highly 
organized  into  official  and  private  groups,  the  dead  hand  of  the  past  still 
lingers.  Group  life  remains  encumbered  by  the  theories  of  organization  and 
administration  which  developed  in  a  feudal  civilization.  We  have  yet  to 
win  our  complete  independence  from  the  past. 

The  more  democratic  life  of  America — as  well  as  the  psychology  and 
the  methods  of  the  scientist,  the  artist,  and  the  inventor — has  revealed  the 
deeper  resources  of  responsibility  when  men  and  women  have  an  oppor- 
tunity to  be  themselves  and  join  with  others  in  pursuit  of  common  goals. 
We  still  have  much  to  learn  of  the  potentials  of  human  beings  and  how 
to  realize  those  potentials.  That  is  an  important  part  of  the  future  of 
democracy.  Administration  must  learn  to  substitute  imagination,  inven- 
tion, understanding,  and  persuasion  for  authority. 

New  Methodology.  A  new  theory,  a  new  language  pattern,  a  new 
intellectual  climate,  a  new  methodology  will  not  be  the  full-blown  product 
of  tomorrow's  labors.  Instead,  its  realization  will  more  probably  flow  from 
the  slower  currents  of  many  partial  contributions  to  a  new  "common  law" 
and  common  practice  in  administration.  This  common  practice  already 
has  had  its  promising  beginning. 

There  is  cumulative  evidence  to  show  that  the  student  and  the  practi- 
tioner of  administration  are  each  growing  conscious  of  the  roots  and  the 
processes  of  behavior  and  motivation.  Preliminary  borrowings  and  tentative 
applications  of  the  findings  of  the  psychologist  and  the  sociologist  are  be- 
coming more  frequent.  In  some  of  the  literature  and  in  some  of  the  prac- 
tice of  administration,  the  shift  in  emphasis  from  the  language  of  authority 
to  the  language  of  democracy  is  quite  pronounced.3  In  others,  the  incon- 
sistency between  the  articulate  premises  of  authority  and  the  inarticulate 
premises  of  democratic  management  is  not  yet  clearly  seen.  The  forms 
and  practices  of  democratic  management  have,  instead,  been  engrafted  with 
greater  or  lesser  skill  upon  the  unchanged  forms  and  habits  of  authority. 

Even  these  latter  instances,  however,  are  signs  of  progress.  The  dynamics  of 

8  See  especially  Lilienthal,  David  E.,  TV  A:  Democracy  on  the  March,  New  York:  Harper, 
1944;  Clapp,  Gordon  and  Others,  Employee  Relations  in  the  Public  Service,  Chicago:  Civil 
Service  Assembly,  1942;  Follctt,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  2. 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  485 

morale,  once  even  partially  released,  tend  to  exert  their  own  educative  force. 
In  still  other  situations  the  new  patterns  are  applied  uncritically,  and  often 
for  management's  transient  or  self-serving  purposes.  Although  such  appli- 
cations are  in  the  main  unsuccessful  and  frequently  self-defeating,  they  too 
on  occasion  have  a  value  not  without  parallel  to  the  process  by  which,  in 
private  enterprise,  the  company  union  sometimes  finds  its  way  to  inde- 
pendence and  maturity. 

Teamworl^.  The  methodology  of  morale  now  includes  a  list  of  tech- 
niques of  respectable  length  and  depth.  Most  of  these  have  been  tested 
in  the  fires  of  application.  Their  worth  and  uses  are  consequently  known 
to  sophisticated  observers  and  practitioners.  Distinctly  prominent  are  the 
several  devices  by  which  the  concept  of  "the  team"  is  gradually  being  sub- 
stituted for  the  unmitigated  concept  of  hierarchy.  These  devices  are  the 
most  promising,  although  the  most  difficult  to  apply.  Their  great  value 
lies  in  the  fact  that  they  strike  at  the  basic  causes  of  static  morale.  Without 
them,  other  devices  are  restricted  to  marginal  influence  upon  morale 
improvement. 

Methods  for  establishing  "the  team"  as  the  action  group  in  public  ad- 
ministration are  many  and  diversified.  One  complex  of  methods  is  designed 
to  increase  the  forms  and  content  of  communication  among  all  levels  of 
the  organization,  emphasizing  especially  the  two-way  function  of  the  chan- 
nels of  communication.4  Staff  indoctrination  is  thus  perpetuated  and 
transformed  into  group  consultation.  Lines  of  command  become  the  ma- 
chinery by  which  preliminary  goals  are  set,  revised,  agreed  upon,  and  made 
into  group  objectives  and  standards  of  accomplishment.  Staff  meetings — 
sterile  institutions  under  the  literal  premises  of  hierarchy— become  dynamic 
centers  of  high  morale  as  skill  and  sincerity  are  nourished  through  their 
successful  development. 

The  written  word  in  the  process  of  communication  is  no  less  important. 
When  the  reports  of  progress  and  achievement  and  the  assignments  of 
general  and  specific  tasks  are  consciously  used  as  instruments  of  consulta- 
tion and  participation  by  and  for  the  whole  group,  their  value  to  morale 
becomes  immeasurably  positive.  In  creating  and  renewing  morale,  the 
need  for  constant  invention  is  imperative.  The  task  of  the  leader  is  the 
imaginative  search  for  new  forms  of  communication  and  the  modified  use  of 
old  forms.  It  is  equally  his  assignment  to  avoid  dependence  upon  once  suc- 
cessful devices  which  have  lost  their  sharp  edge  or  have  been  made  inappro- 
priate by  time  or  circumstance. 

Leadership.    Another  category  of  morale  methods  is  the  group  which 

4  For  two  suggestive  expositions  of  the  purposes  and  the  art  of  communication,  see  Cor- 
son,  John  J.,  "The  Role  of  Communication  in  the  Process  of  Administration,"  Public  Admin- 
istration Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  7  #.;  Federal  Security  Agency,  Social  Security  Board,  Train- 
ing Bulletin  No.  2,  Making  Staff  Meetings  More  Useful,  Washington,  March,  1946  (mimeo- 
graphed). Sec  also  above  Ch.  18,  "The  Tasks  of  Middle  Management,"  sec.  2,  "Supporting. 
Top  Direction." 


486  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

recognizes  the  differential  functions  of  the  several  levels  of  an  organization 
in  the  creation  and  maintenance  of  morale.  These  methods  identify  the 
subtle  role  of  leadership  in  its  various  forms  and  grades  of  responsibility — 
in  particular :  the  executive  task,  the  special  contribution  of  middle  manage- 
ment, and  the  crucial  role  of  the  first-line  supervisor.  The  metamorphosis 
from  authoritarian  to  democratic  management  depends  almost  exclusively 
upon  the  skill  with  which  the  commander  transforms  himself  into  the 
leader.  All  the  pressures  of  convention  and  all  the  lines  of  least  resistance 
move  him  toward  the  continued  use  of  formal  authority.  Nevertheless, 
he  must  want  to  be  the  leader  rather  than  the  commander. 

The  role  of  leader  is  more  difficult  than  any  other.  Except  by  the  ob- 
sessed or  the  inspired,  it  is  therefore  reluctantly  adopted.  The  leader  has 
no  vacation  from  his  task,  no  gadgets  to  manipulate  defensively,  no  alibis 
available.5  Despite  his  greater  satisfactions  with  success,  he  must  constantly 
practice  the  art  of  anonymity  in  his  methods  of  leadership.  Otherwise  he 
becomes  the  "big  boss."  All  this  requires  a  sense  of  dedication  rarely  en- 
countered in  the  market  place  of  traditional  managers  and  supervisors. 
The  finding  and  training  of  leaders  is,  accordingly,  one  of  the  main 
burdens  of  those  who  aspire  to  promote  the  growth  and  universal  exten- 
sion of  democratic  management. 

The  specific  elements  of  leadership  appropriate  to  democratic  group- 
performance  have  received  little  more  than  peripheral  attention  in  manage- 
ment literature.  The  by-paths  of  military  and  other  authoritarian  traditions 
have  proved  too  inviting.  Jefferson's  precepts,  long  neglected,  are  only  now 
tardily  being  taken  up.  The  discoveries  of  the  psychologist  are  only  now 
verifying  democratic  premises.  Small  beginnings  are  only  now  spreading 
into  more  confident  application  on  broader  scenes.  Among  these,  the  ex- 
periments undertaken  by  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  deserve  pioneer 
status.  Other  efforts  await  only  the  conclusive  evidence  of  their  success 
and  merit.6 

Group  Development.  The  following  excerpt  from  a  kit  for  supervisors 
issued  by  the  Office  of  Price  Administration  is  a  good  example  of  docu- 
mentation of  the  emerging  tendencies  for  the  promotion  of  leadership  and 
self-development : 

MARKS  OF  SUPERIOR  GROUP  PERFORMANCE 

The  press  of  operational  responsibilities  commonly  diverts  attention 
from  our  leadership  role.  Moreover,  leadership  is  such  a  personal  matter 
that  it  is  difficult  to  evaluate  objectively.  Yet  it  is  leadership  that  trans- 
forms a  number  of  individuals  into  a  team,  and  it  is  only  as  a  team  that 
we  and  our  staff  can  effectively  discharge  our  responsibilities. 


5  See  particularly  Tead,  The  Art  of  Leadership,  cit.  above  in  note  2;  Stone,  Donald  C., 
"Notes  on  the  Government  Executive:  His  Role  and  Methods,"  Public  Administration  Review, 
1945,  Vol.  5,  p.  210  ff.'9  Niles,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  2. 

6  Sec,   for   instance,   the   ideas   developed   by   Bradford,   Leland  P.   and   Lippitt,  Ronald, 
"Building  a  Democratic  Work  Group,"  Personnel,  1945,  Vol.  22,  p.  142  ff. 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  487 

The  best  way  to  study  our  leadership  is  to  measure  it  against  the  per- 
formance of  our  group.  Following  are  some  criteria  of  group  perform- 
ance. It  is  not  assumed  that  many  groups  will  rate  high  on  all  items. 
These  items  can,  however,  help  us  to  analyze  the  performance  of  our 
group  and  our  success  as  their  leaders.  Upon  the  basis  of  such  an  an- 
alysis, we  may  discover  ways  in  which  our  leadership  should  develop. 

A.  Employee  Performance 

1.  The  members  of  the  staff  show  initiative,  resourcefulness,  and  im- 
agination in  dealing  with  problem  situations.   They  are  skillful  in  an- 
alysis of  problems  and  inventive  in  solutions. 

2.  They  have  a  whole-hearted  interest  in  their  work  and  a  sense  of 
responsibility,  not  only  for  their  individual  job,  but  for  the  programs  of 
their  shop  and  the  agency  as  a  whole. 

3.  They  are  eager  to  learn  and  grow  in  their  job.  They  know  what 
they  need  and  want  to  learn  and  why  they  want  to  learn  it. 

4.  Employees  have  confidence  in  themselves  but  at  the  same  time  are 
objective,  analytical,  and  critical  about  their  performance. 

B.  Supervisory  Performance 

1.  The  supervisor  encourages  employees  to  make  suggestions,  develop 
ideas,  and  plan  for  improving  operations.  He  helps  them  test  out  and 
evaluate  objectively  their  suggestions  and  ideas,  and  where  possible  ac- 
cepts and  acts  upon  them. 

2.  The  supervisor  depends  more  upon  the  employees'  attitudes  toward 
their  work  as  disciplinary  controls  and  less  upon  his  own  authority  and 
arbitrary  "dos"  and  "don'ts." 

C.  Relations  Within  the  Group 

1.  The  staff  works  together  cooperatively  as  a  team  with  a  large 
measure  of  common  understanding  and  common  purpose.  Each  member 
shares  actively  in  group  decision,  policy  making,  and  planning.  He  sees 
his  individual  job  in  relation  to  the  total  program. 

2.  There  is  mutual  respect  and  friendliness  among  supervisors  and 
subordinates.   They  are  interested  in  each  other  as  persons.   The  work 
atmosphere  is  cordial  and  congenial. 

It  might  be  helpful  from  time  to  time  to  rate  your  group  on  these 
items,  using  a  scale  from  1  to  5.  In  this  way  you  can  note  improvements 
in  your  leadership. 

Wording  Together.  No  less  productive  of  morale  than  are  teamwork, 
leadership,  and  group  development  are  the  constructive  gropings  for  collab- 
oration between  public  management  and  the  organized  rank  and  file  of 
the  group.  The  weight  of  the  old  approach  here,  of  course,  as  in  private 
management,7  has  been  toward  the  antithesis  of  collaboration.  The  tradi- 
tion of  authority  and  command  in  management  has  generated  a  reciprocal 
tradition — the  grouping  of  employees  into  combative  and  hostile  organi- 
zations. The  authoritarian  attitude  has  met  employee  aspirations  for  active 
participation  in  the  whole  administrative  process  by  many  types  of  resist- 

7  For  a  significant  departure  from  this  tradition,  see  Walters,  J.  E.,  Personnel  Relations, 
New  York:  Ronald  Press,  1945. 


488  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

ance  and  defense.  The  sovereignty  of  the  state  has  been  freely  invoked, 
The  techniques  of  paternalism  have  been  widely  used.  And  when  further 
ramparts  were  needed,  public  management  has  marked  out  narrow  juris- 
dictional  areas  of  employee  consultation. 

Government-employee  organizations  have  tried  to  defeat  these  tactics 
with  countermeasures  of  open  or  concealed  waffare.  The  result  has  been, 
generally,  that  morale  was  sacrificed  upon  the  altar  of  authority.  Slowly, 
however,  the  rank  and  file  have  pushed  forward  the  boundaries  of  recog- 
nition. As  concessions  have  gradually  softened  the  forms  of  resistance, 
collaboration  has  brought  forth  some  of  the  minimum  conditions  of  demo- 
cratic management.  Particularly  in  the  last  decade  have  the  habits  of 
formal  relations  and  hostility  been  progressively  abandoned. 

Substantial  headway  has  thus  been  made  toward  the  removal  of  nega- 
tive factors,  but  only  fractional  advance  has  occurred  in  the  development  of 
machinery  for  fruitful  employee  partnership  in  public  administration. 
Negotiation,  rather  than  participation,  is  still  the  order  of  the  day.  There  is 
real  promise,  nonetheless,  that  progress  may  now  be  by  geometrical  pro- 
gression. Certainly  the  ferment  of  increased  collaboration  in  strategic 
areas  is  fully  at  work.  Both  management  and  union  now  need  to  give 
their  energies  to  the  invention  of  efficient  and  economical  machinery  by 
which  the  rank  and  file  may  contribute  their  maximum  responsibility  to 
the  attainment  of  higher  group  morale.8 

Union  Attitudes.  An  illustration  of  employee  thinking  about  conditions 
of  good  morale  is  the  following  statement  published  by  the  National  Fed- 
eration of  Federal  Employees,  a  body  not  affiliated  with  either  the  Ameri- 
can Federation  of  Labor  or  the  Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations:9 

HINTS  FOR  GOOD  ADMINISTRATORS  AND  FOR  GOOD  FEDERAL  EMPLOYEES 

Administrators  Employees 

Fight  for   your  employees.    See   that     Fight  for  your  supervisor.   See  that  he 
they  get  a  square  deal.    Be  loyal  to     gets  a  square  deal.   Be  loyal  to  him. 
them. 

Promote  your  employees  as  rapidly  as     Boost  your  employer's  stock, 
is  justified  and  possible. 

Promote  one  of  your  own  employees,      Work  hard  to  improve  your  efficiency 
an  insider,  to  new  and  available  jobs;     so  as  to  become  qualified  for  a  better 
do  not  bring  in  outsiders  and   place     position, 
them  above  insiders  of  equal  efficiency. 

Promote   insiders  of  greater  seniority      Be  alert  to  promote  objectives  of  your 
over  those  of  lesser  seniority,  provided      service  at  all  times, 
the  qualifications  are  equally  good. 

8  For  evidence  of  this  progress  in  theory  and  practice,  see  Clapp,  op.  cit.  above  in  note 
3;  National  Civil  Service  League,  Employee  Organizations  in  the  Public  Service,  New  York, 
1946;  Golden,  Clinton  S.  and  Ruttenberg,  Harold  J.,  The  Dynamics  of  Industrial  Democracy. 
New  York:  Harper,  1942.  See  also  below  Ch.  24,  "Personnel  Standards,"  sec.  6,  "Employee 
Relations." 

*  Federal  Employee,  1945,  Vol.  30,  No.  2,  p.  8  (by  permission  of  the  editor). 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 


489 


Administrators 

Be  economical,  but  remember  the  best 
economy  is  a  staff  of  good  workers, 
well  paid,  possessed  of  high  morale, 
and  effecting  maximum  production. 

Know  your  people  personally,  as  many 
of  them  as  possible.  Take  a  personal 
interest  in  their  welfare. 

Avoid  issuance  of  conflicting  instruc- 
tions. When  new  work  assignments 
are  made,  check  on  previous  obligations 
already  assumed  by  those  to  whom  the 
orders  are  issued. 

Insofar  as  practicable  explain  the 
reasons  for  things,  but  do  not  argue. 


Eliminate  dead-end  jobs.  They  are  a 
sign  of  ineffective  organization. 

Be  prompt  to  transfer,  reclassify,  or  sep- 
arate from  the  service  any  unsatisfac- 
tory employee.  Do  not  blame  anyone 
but  yourself  if  you  have  such  employees 
in  your  administrative  unit. 

Encourage  organization  and  coopera- 
tion on  the  part  of  your  employees  in 
unions  for  improvement  of  working 
conditions  and  social  and  economic  wel- 
fare, credit  unions,  hospital  guilds,  or 
other  groups.  Go  in  with  them  if  the 
rules  permit.  Show  them  your  interest 
and  give  them  your  help. 

Take  your  employees  into  your  confi- 
dence. Hold  frequent  conferences. 
Keep  in  touch  with  your  personnel 
office. 

Make  the  most  of  yourself  and  your 
outfit.  Folks  like  to  work  for  a  suc- 
cessful administrator,  strong  enough 
to  get  the  job  done,  protect  his  em- 
ployees, and  advance  his  organization. 

Cut  out  all  possible  red  tape,  but  retain 
control  of  all  operations  so  the  work 
will  advance  effectively  and  with  cer- 
tainty. 


Employees 

Help  to  get  the  job  done  with  the  great- 
est economy  of  materials,  time,  and 
energy. 

While  no  employer  likes  an  apple  poi 
isher,  the  employee  should  go  at  least 
half  way.  Supervisors  are  human. 

If  impossible  assignments  are  received, 
tell  the  supervisor  quickly.  Do  not 
apologize,  make  excuses,  or  alibi  when 
work  is  not  done. 

Call  possible  improvements  to  the  su- 
pervisor's attention,  but  do  not  argue. 
Go  ahead  and  get  the  job  done  to  the 
best  of  your  ability. 

Do  not  be  satisfied  with  any  dead-end 
job.  Build  up  your  qualifications  so 
that  you  can  advance. 

If  your  record  is  unsatisfactory,  cooper- 
ate with  the  responsible  administrator 
to  secure  a  transfer,  reclassification,  or 
separation  from  the  service  so  you  can 
find  your  proper  place. 

Join  and  promote  employee  cooper- 
atives  such  as  unions  for  improvement 
of  working  conditions,  social  and  eco- 
nomic welfare,  credit  unions,  hospital 
guilds  and  the  like. 


When  you  have  a  grievance  take  it  to 
the  supervisor  first.  Give  him  a  chance 
to  straighten  things  out. 

Give  individual  loyalty  to  employer  and 
organization.  Put  all  you've  got  into 
it,  so  it  can  really  get  the  job  done  and 
advance. 

Pay  meticulous  attention  to  actual 
paper  requirements.  A  certain  amount 
of  red  tape  is  essential  to  the  smooth 
functioning  of  a  large  organization. 
After  all,  your  salary  check  is  paper 
work!  Let  the  supervisor  know  when 
you  discover  a  valid  short  cut. 


490  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

Incentives.  Much  attention  and  experimentation  have  been  given  to  a 
class  of  morale  methods  which  are  concerned  with  identifying  and  using 
systems  of  incentives  and  rewards.  Conventionally,  two  types  of  incentives 
and  rewards  are  identified — the  economic  and  the  noneconomic.  Exten- 
sive analysis,  particularly  in  private  management,  has  tended  to  establish 
the  fact  that  in  individual  motivation  these  two  are  not  only  inextricably 
mixed  but  that  they  also  have  approximately  equal  significance.  In  public 
employment,  it  has  been  assumed  that  nonfinancial  incentives  count  more 
heavily  than  financial.  Security,  the  prestige  of  public  service,  the  evolution 
of  career  systems,  and  the  use  of  objective  standards  for  individual  advance- 
ment have  all  been  offered  as  substitutes  for  higher  monetary  awards  in 
private  industry,  c^ 

The  sharp  limits  that  restrict  the  validity  of  this  thesis  have  led  to  the 
introduction,  in  more  recent  years,  of  various  additional  financial  and  non- 
financial  incentives  for  public  employees.  Salary  increases  for  meritorious 
service  and  cash  awards  for  outstanding  employee-suggestions  have  become 
regular  features  of  administrative  practice.  Nonfinancial  incentives  have 
also  been  increasingly  emphasized.  Official  recognition  of  distinguished 
service  has  been  formalized  in  service  awards  and  other  official  document* 
and  insignia.  Most  incentive  systems,  whether  financial  or  nonfinancial, 
are  still  in  rudimentary  form.  This  is  due  mainly  to  awareness  of  the  fact 
that  they  are  only  supplementary  morale  devices.  As  such,  however,  they 
warrant  fuller  elaboration. 

In  the  absence  of  more  basic  morale  generators,  incentive  systems  serve 
largely  to  ameliorate  the  harsher  forms  of  administration  and  to  provide 
management  with  "showcase"  demonstrations  of  democratic  intentions. 
Under  these  conditions,  they  invite  and  receive  the  suspicion  or  indifference 
of  the  group  rather  than  recognition  as  important  parts  of  the  work  en- 
vironment. In  another  setting,  governed  by  good  will  without  valor,  in- 
centive systems  may  represent  superficial  comprehension  by  management 
of  the  basic  factors  in  human  motivation.  When  offered  as  a  deliberately 
contrived  but  measured  concession  to  democratic  management,  such  sys- 
tems invariably  disappoint  their  creators.  Only  as  a  bona  fide  expression  of 
genuine  effort  toward  democratic  management  are  they  worth  the  cost  of  in- 
stallation and  administration.10 

Performance  Standards.  Incentive  systems  point  the  way  toward  a  more 
important  method  of  morale  improvement.  The  work  group  needs,  and 
will  invariably  respond  to,  objective  standards  of  performance.  These  must 
be  standards  agreed  upon  by  the  group,  not  simply  the  ex  cathedra  standards 
of  management.  Here  again,  the  process  of  creation  has  been  slow. 

Standards  have  been  characteristically  established  by  statistical  averages, 
by  the  pace-setter  in  the  group,  by  "time  studies,"  or  by  the  standard  of 

10  See  Roethlisbergcr,  Management  and  Morale,  cit.  above  in  note  2.  Sec  also  above 
Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec.  5,  "Supervision  and  Employee  Initiative." 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  491 

maximum  profits.  These  are  not  the  standards  which  increase  morale. 
Standards  useful  to  morale  are  those  whose  logic  and  reasonableness  ap- 
peal to  the  group — those  which  have  been  set  by  the  process  of  participation 
and  agreement  within  the  group.  Standards  arrived  at  in  any  other  way 
invite  sabotage  of  quality  if  not  of  quantity  of  performance.11 

Production  standards,  though  frequently  used  as  the  main  test  of  morale, 
are  in  fact  deceptive  instruments  of  diagnosis.  Production  is  the  resultant  of 
many  variables.  Low  production  is  the  sign  of  pathology  in  collaboration. 
But  a  complete  diagnosis  may  require  scrutiny  of  the  total  environment 
of  the  group.  Effective  therapy  as  a  rule  involves  correction  of  the  modes 
of  organization  and  of  the  exercise  of  authority  by  supervisor  and  manager. 
Only  such  correction  may  release  the  creative  potential  of  the  group. 

Essentiality  of  Purpose.  In  public  administration,  the  manager  and  the 
supervisor  have  at  hand  a  morale  potential  greater  than  that  tapped  by  any 
of  the  methods  thus  far  mentioned.  Theirs  is  the  rare  opportunity  to  use  the 
ends  and  purposes  of  society  in  their  direct  relationships  to  the  objectives  of 
the  groups  they  lead.  Public  service  can  be  seen  as  an  indispensable  means 
by  which  the  community  attains  its  aims. 

Participation  in  an  economic  stabilization  program,  for  instance,  whose 
effects  reach  every  American — indeed  help  determine  world  prosperity — 
has  a  significance  beside  which  merely  private  objectives  pale  into  sheer 
inconsequence.  The  same  is  true  of  participation  in  a  program  of  social 
security,  in  the  definition  of  the  rights  of  labor,  in  a  program  of  service  and 
information  to  American  business,  in  the  conduct  of  foreign  affairs.  All 
these  undertakings  are  charged  with  such  implications  that  when  employees 
are  aroused  to  the  importance  of  what  they  do,  the  effect  upon  morale  is 
electrifying. 

Unfortunately,  too  many  public  employees  are  helped  to  see  only  a 
little  way  beyond  their  own  desks.  Their  activity  becomes  a  dull  routine; 
their  self-esteem  is  smothered  by  hard  layers  of  hierarchy.  Thus  is  lost  a 
great  and  everpresent  morale  potential. 

3.  THE  MODES  OF  DISCIPLINE 

Aims  of  Discipline.  The  modes  of  discipline  are  best  appraised  in  the 
perspective  of  democratic  management.  Thus  viewed,  they  obviously  rep- 
resent techniques  for  handling  the  crises  flowing  from  the  breakdown  of 
morale.  Too  often  discipline  is  relied  upon  to  bolster  the  edifice  of  com- 
mand, to  control  the  deviations  from  established  authority,  and  to  induce 
conformity  as  a  substitute  for  agreement.  When  the  modes  of  discipline 

11  For  the  most  interesting  and  promising  recent  approach,  see  United  States  Bureau  of 
the  Budget,  Work.  Simplification  as  Exemplified  by  the  Work  Simplification  Program  of  the 
17.  5.  Bureau  of  the  Budget,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1945,  Publication  No.  91; 
Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "Looking  at  Under-all  Management,"  Public  Administration  Review 
1944,  Vol.  4,  p.  368  ff. 


492  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

arc  employed  for  these  purposes,  the  frequency  of  their  use  supplies  an 
index  to  the  state  of  group  morale.  Conversely,  self-enforcing  discipline 
is  a  function  of  high  morale. 

However,  even  within  the  framework  of  democratic  management,  ma- 
chinery of  discipline  has  its  place.  As  first  aid  to  treat  the  failures  of 
leadership  or  of  individual  performance,  discipline  may  provide  the  starting 
point  for  constructive  morale  action.  This  means  that  the  most  important 
matter  about  discipline  is  the  purpose  and  the  manner  of  its  use.  Purpose 
raises  the  question  of  the  major  premise  of  discipline.  Is  it  to  preserve  the 
structure  of  command  ?  Or  is  it  to  contribute  to  the  improvement  of  group 
cooperation  and  morale?  These  are  not  so  much  inconsistent  premises  as 
they  are  competing  emphases.  The  problem  resolves  itself  into  the  ques- 
tion: Which  is  major;  which  is  minor? 

The  fact  that  the  traditional  pattern  exalts  the  relation  of  discipline  to 
command  has  compelled  the  growth  of  many  ameliorative  safeguards — 
formal  statement  of  "cause"  of  disciplinary  action,  right  of  hearing,  right  of 
appeal.  The  more  conventional  literature  of  discipline  puts  stress  on  these 
safeguards  without  giving  much  consideration  to  the  premise  which  makes 
the  safeguards  so  necessary.  The  current  task  is  to  infuse  into  the  subject 
the  fresh  vitality  of  the  new  concept  of  democratic  morale. 

A  more  positive  approach  to  discipline  would  treat  it  as  the  systematic 
developmentof  the  understandings,  values,  skills,  and  attitudes  involved 
in  effective  participation  in  institutional  processes.  Thu*;  discipline  would 
assume  an  educative  rather  than  a  punitive  functionVHere  we  could  per- 
ceive once  more  the  sharp  distinction  between  the  democratic  and  the 
authoritarian  versions  of  administration.  We  should  remind  ourselves  that 
morale  entails  balance,  flexibility,  maturity,  continuity,  persistence  against 
adversity,  and  capacity  for  constant  renewal. 

Such  morale  comes  only  from  untiring  and  positive  discipline  in  the 
arts  and  manners  of  participation,  of  teamwork.  Discipline  in  this  sense 
is  a  product  of  democratic  leadership  that  concentrates  on  education,  per- 
suasion, and  consultation  rather  than  on  authority  and  control.  The  dis- 
ciplinary techniques  of  the  reprimand,  the  demotion,  the  dismissal,  together 
with  efficiency  rating,  assume  their  proper  and  relatively  minor  roles  of 
complementing  the  positive  appeals  of  leadership. 

Disciplinary  Restraints.  In  the  public  service,  discipline  is  also  repre- 
sented in  other  institutional  forms.  Traditionally,  these  take  the  shape  of 
more  or  less  restrictive  codes  of  behavior  imposed  upon  the  employee  by 
statute  or  civil  service  rule,  or  by  norms  of  conduct  originating  in  the 
atmosphere  of  popular  suspicion  and  fear  which  government  has  inherited 
from  its  authoritarian  past.  Such  codes  are  dubious  instruments  of  dis- 
cipline since  their  more  drastic  provisions  have  no  roots  in  agreement  or 
acceptance  by  those  whom  they  are  intended  to  control. 

Legal  devices  to  hold  in  check  an  imagined  menace  of  bureaucratic 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  493 

partisanship  in  politics  or  to  neutralize  the  democratic  influence  of  the 
government  employee  in  his  role  of  private  citizen,  may  have  demoralizing 
effects.  Significantly,  action  under  these  codes  tends  toward  occasional 
peaks  of  excited  application  and  longer  valleys  of  desuetude.12  In  the  larger 
perspective,  formal  disciplinary  clauses  often  fail  in  their  positive  purposes 
and  simultaneously  retard  the  growth  of  democratic  morale  in  many  areas. 
Far  more  important  are  the  standards  of  self-restraint  and  propriety  that 
emerge  naturally  in  the  consciousness  of  a  career  service. 

Political  Aspects.  Disciplinary  rules  usually  prohibit  public  employees 
from  playing  a  part  in  political  campaigns  and  in  party  management, 
aside  from  defining  the  scope  of  their  freedom  to  make  political  contribu- 
tions. To  some  extent,  these  rules  have  a  protective  intent — to  reduce  politi- 
cal pressure  on  government  personnel.  However,  injunction  and  protection 
may  often  overlap  in  strange  ways. 

As  an  example  of  the  dilemmas  posed  by  the  traditional  codes,  the  fol- 
lowing statement  by  a  member  of  the  United  States  Civil  Service  Commis- 
sion before  a  congressional  committee  on  employee  activities  which  "may 
in  a  sense  be  political"  but  are  not  prohibited  by  either  the  Hatch  Act  of 
1939  or  the  civil  service  rules  is  instructive:13 

The  Hatch  Act  by  a  direct  provision  in  section  9  (a)  fully  protects  a 
Federal  employee's  right  to  vote  as  he  may  choose  and  to  express  his 
opinions  on  all  political  subjects  and  candidates.  Section  18  of  the  act 
definitely  provides  that  Federal  employees  may  actively  participate  in 
wholly  nonpartisan  local  elections  and  may  work  for  or  against  any  gen- 
eral question  that  is  to  be  decided  at  the  polls  by  the  voters.  In  addition 
to  these,  it  has  been  ruled  that  a  Federal  employee  is  permitted  to  engage 
in  the  following,  notwithstanding  the  provisions  of  the  Hatch  Act  and 
the  civil  service  rules: 

Attend  open  public  political  meetings  as  a  spectator;  make  voluntary 
contributions  to  a  political  party  general  campaign  fund;  become  a  mem- 
ber and  attend  meetings  of  a  political  club;  wear  a  campaign  badge  or 
button;  display  a  candidate's  campaign  photograph  in  his  home  or  auto- 
mobile; sign  a  political  party  candidate's  nominating  petition  as  an 
individual. 

Thus  are  general  rights,  once  restricted,  slowly  reestablished  segment  by 
segment  in  a  reluctant  catalog  of  interpretation. 

Service  Ethics.  The  methods  of  emancipation  from  purely  negative 
institutional  restraints  imposed  on  government  employees  are  to  some  degree 
already  spelled  out.  They  may  be  described  in  different  main  categories. 

12  For  an  analysis  of  one  significant  segment  of  this  problem,  see  Sayre,  Wallace  S., 
"Political  Neutrality,'*  in  Morstein  Marx,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  2,  p.  202  ff. 

13  House  Committee  on  Appropriations,  Hearings  on  the  Independent  Offices  Appropria- 
tion  Bill   for    1947,   p.    1111,   79th   Con*.,   2d   Sess.,   Washington,    1946.    Sec  also  Howard, 
L.  V.,  "Federal  Restrictions  upon  the  Political  Activity  of  Government  Employees,"  American 
Political  Science  Review,  1941,  Vol.  35,  p.  470  ff.;  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "Comparative  Ad- 
ministrative Law:    Political  Activity  of  Civil  Servants,"  Virginia  Law  Review,  1942,  Vol.  29, 
P.  52  ff. 


494  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

The  common  objective— as  has  already  been  suggested— is  the  substitution 
of  a  body  of  service  ethics,  providing  positive  aims  and  voluntary  standards 
of  behavior,  for  the  restrictive  codes  of  control  nearly  exclusively  relied 
upon  hitherto.  </ 

One  method  would  be  the  official  publication  of  basic  postulates  for 
public-service  conduct.  This  method  is  best  illustrated  in  several  of  the 
provisions  of  the  Weimar  Constitution  of  1919  and  in  the  more  relevant 
declaration  of  the  Michigan  Civil  Service  Act  of  1937 :14 

Every  state  employee  shall  fulfill  conscientiously,  according  to  the  con- 
stitution and  the  laws,  the  duties  of  the  office  conferred  upon  him  and 
shall  prove  himself  in  his  behavior  inside  and  outside  the  office  worthy 
of  the  esteem  which  his  profession  requires.  In  his  official  activity,  the 
state  employee  shall  pursue  the  common  good  and  not  only  be  impartial 
but  so  act  as  not  to  endanger  his  impartiality  nor  to  give  occasion  for  dis- 
trust of  his  impartiality. 

Postulates  of  such  breadth  and  universal  validity  inspire  creative  response. 
They  draw  forth  implicit  sentiments  of  public  service.  Their  essence  is  the 
establishment  of  goals  and  norms  whose  appropriateness  is  satisfactorily 
self-evident. 

There  is,  however,  a  corollary  essential  to  the  full  realization  of  this 
method.  The  authors  of  such  basic  postulates  of  behavior  must  refrain 
from  weakening  the  principal  pronouncements  by  the  inclusion  or  subse- 
quent addition  of  wholly  restrictive  lists  of  imposed  conditions.  These 
serve  only  to  rob  the  higher  postulates  of  their  full  meaning  and  to  limit 
the  aspirations  of  the  public  servant. 

Evocation  of  Self-Discipline.  Another  method  is  the  promotion  of 
career  ethics  in  the  many  professional  segments  of  the  public  service,  in- 
cluding the  administrative  personnel  in  the  more  specific  sense.  The  evo- 
cation of  self-discipline  in  the  form  of  professional  codes  of  ethics  is  evident 
in  many  contemporary  practices.  Professional  solidarity  in  its  positive 
manifestations  furnishes  guides  to  willing  deference  to  the  public  interest. 

The  International  City  Managers  Association,  for  instance,  has  built  a 
sound  and  widely  applicable  tradition  in  its  many  years  of  emphasis  upon 
the  professional  standards  to  govern  the  official  conduct  of  the  city  man- 
ager. The  special  significance  of  its  approach  as  a  method  of  positive  dis- 
cipline is  in  the  manner  of  its  origin  and  growth.  These  are  standards  of 
behavior  created  by  the  group,  though  not  without  the  labor  of  leadership. 
In  their  final  institutional  form  they  represent  an  agreed-upon  declaration 
of  group  aims.15 

14  Sec.  23  of  the  act 

15  An  example  of  the  "strain  of  formation"  is  provided  by  the  strivings  of  the  "atomic" 
scientists  to  find  a  blueprint  for  their  basic  responsibilities  as  a  group. 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  495 

4.  MORALE  AND  INSTITUTIONAL  PATTERN 

Organizational  Structure  and  Concerted  Action.  We  have  been  critical 
of  some  of  the  effects  of  hierarchy  and  associated  forms  of  authoritarian 
administration.  This  was  not  to  underestimate  the  needs  for  organization, 
for  structure,  and  for  clarity  of  command.  On  the  contrary,  what  we  seek 
is  a  new  perspective  on  structure  and  its  uses.  As  Paul  Appleby  has  put  it, 
"Getting  agreement  on  action  has  its  beginning  in  structure.  Concerted 
action  becomes  possible  only  by  organizing  for  action.  .  .  .  structure  comes 
first  and  remains  basic."16  Thus  the  main  difficulty  lies  in  the  vast  exag- 
geration given  in  administrative  literature  to  hierarchy  and  other  embodi- 
ments of  authority. 

In  Appleby 's  words:17 

Administration  is  somehow  a  respectable  word  while  "coordination" 
seems  to  be  disreputable.  Yet  administration  always  proceeds  through 
coordination.  To  coordinate  is  to  bring  into  common  action,  and  this  is  a 
reasonably  adequate  general  definition  of  administration.  Administra- 
tion is  thought  of  popularly  in  much  too  simple  terms — as  management 
and,  increasing  the  distortion,  in  the  military  or  authoritarian  tradition. 
Psychologists  and  administrators  alike  have  come  increasingly  to  realize 
that  management  consists  much  less  in  giving  orders  than  in  inducing 
or  in  organizing  to  secure  agreement.  When  the  process  is  thus  under- 
stood, orders  are  seen  as  the  formulation  of  what  has  been  or  will  be 
agreed  to.  ...  The  tendency  among  the  uninitiated  is  to  feel  that  if 
someone  would  only  issue  the  proper  orders  or  if  only  someone  were 
clothed  with  sufficient  authority,  there  would  be  no  need  of  coordina- 
tion and  everything  would  become  a  matter  of  "simple  administration." 

All  organization  theory,  in  a  larger  sense,  aims  at  the  essential  recon- 
ciliation of  the  demands  of  structure  and  command  with  the  necessities  of 
group  participation  and  agreement.  Structure  is  basic,  but  it  tends  to  be 
static.  Morale  is  indispensable,  but  it  tends  to  be  fluid.  The  correct  balance 
between  structure  and  morale,  then,  is  that  which  provides  form  and  di- 
rection to  the  dynamics  of  self-realization  and  group  expression. 

Balance  of  Structure  and  Morale.  The  reconciliation  or  balance  between 
structure  and  morale  is  discovered  only  by  constant  recxamination  of  the 
precision  with  which  existing  organization  reflects  the  needs  of  group 
purpose  and  group  participation.  This  perpetual  scrutiny  of  organization 
properly  begins  with  a  searching  question:  How  effectively  does  current 
structure  and  hierarchy  express  the  collective  objective? 

Except  perhaps  for  the  very  moment  of  its  first  creation,  organization 
always  lags  behind  the  expression  of  evolving  group  purpose^  Invariably, 
therefore,  the  drag  of  unexamined  structure  is  backward.  Organization 
is  forever  out  of  date.  Its  rebuilding  or  adaptation  is  a  constant  necessity. 

Organization  in  Action.  From  this  first  inquiry,  the  continued  reconsid- 

*6  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  p.  92,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 
17  Ibid.,  p.  78  (by  permission  of  the  publisher) . 


496  MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE 

eration  of  structure  proceeds  to  an  appraisal  of  organization  in  action.  Does 
it  still  truly  provide  the  mechanics  of  consultation  and  communication 
which  are  essential  to  group  morale?  Have  the  arteries  of  participation 
hardened?  Have  the  signs  and  facts  of  agreement  diminished?  Have  the 
goals  set  become  too  easy  of  accomplishment  and  is  their  attainment  no 
longer  impressive  to  the  group?  Has  leadership  sunk  to  the  plateau  of 
amiable  ratification  of  casual  group  proposals?  These  are  the  diagnostic 
questions  in  the  reassessment  of  structure  in  action.  The  findings  must  be 
applied  ever  anew  to  the  redefinition  of  organization  forms. 

Structure  is  progressively  reconciled  with  morale  when  the  process  of 
reconsideration  produces  repeated  emphasis  upon  participation.  Participa- 
tion is  the  bridge  between  the  structure  and  the  group.  Its  manifestations 
are  productive  to  the  degree  to  which  they  are  at  once  purposeful  and  in- 
formal. Structure,  then,  in  many  ways  needs  to  be  consciously  subordinated. 
It  is  most  efficient  when  it  gives  direction  unobtrusively,  when  the  group 
feels  its  presence  in  substance,  not  in  form. 

Effects  of  Specialization.  Modern  organization  suffers  from  excessive 
accommodation  to  the  dogma  of  specialization.  Effective  operation,  particu- 
larly in  the  complex  tasks  of  modern  government,  requires  the  proficiency 
and  skill  which  comes  from  specialization.  However,  specialization  is  apt 
to  be  separatist,  to  be  narrowly  conceived,  to  isolate  its  practitioners  from  all 
others.18 

Thus  organizational  theory  is  confronted  with  the  additional  imperative 
to  integrate  and  simultaneously  identify  the  specialized  parts  with  the  whole. 
The  reconciliation  of  structure  with  morale  therefore  imposes  a  further  task 
upon  the  art  of  leadership.  It  is  the  conscious  emphasis  upon  interrelation- 
ships, upon  the  processes  of  inter  communication —particularly  the  methods 
by  which  the  specialized  parts  participate  in  the  shaping  of  general  objec- 
tives, the  evaluation  of  general  accomplishments,  and  the  appropriate  sub- 
ordination of  all  the  structural  components  to  the  overriding  purpose  of  the 
group. 

Discipline  as  Affirmative  Pressure.  Structure  and  command,  as  we  have 
seen,  lean  toward  self-preservation  and  aggrandizement.  In  this  inclination, 
discipline  in  its  negative  forms  is  most  frequently  invoked.  Mitigation  of 
such  tendencies  by  awareness  of  the  necessities  of  democratic  morale  is  a 
further  problem  in  theory  and  practice. 

The  regressive  uses  of  discipline  are  ubiquitous.  Administrative  archi- 
tects who  seek  the  optimum  balance  between  structure  and  morale  must 
accordingly  look  toward  the  identification  and  isolation  of  disciplinary  ele- 
ments. The  whole  range  of  disciplinary  sanctions,  from  the  reprimand  to  the 
dismissal,  presents  opportunities  for  reciprocity  and  accommodation  of  insti- 
tutional interests.  When  rightly  seized  upon,  these  opportunities  may 

18  C/.  above  Ch.  9,  "The  Departmental  System,"  sec.  1,  "General  Features." 


MORALE  AND  DISCIPLINE  497 

provide  the  moment  and  the  means  for  fruitful  exercise  of  leadership  and 
collaboration.  Such  objectives  are  realized  only  when  discipline  is  viewed 
as  one  of  the  affirmative  pressures  toward  collective  ends.  In  the  hands  of 
skillful  leadership,  the  reprimand,  for  example,  is  not  a  coercive  weapon 
but  a  tool  for  the  promotion  of  mutual  understanding,  objective  evaluation, 
and  new  direction. 

Morale  and  structure  are  the  complementary  halves  of  administration. 
In  the  important  sphere  of  modern  public  administration,  their  unity  can 
be  as  productive  as  the  democratic  idea  itself,  which  released  the  Western 
world  from  its  bondage  to  institutions  congealed  by  time  into  the  tight 
shackles  of  feudalism.  Nor  is  their  unity  a  goal  beyond  our  day  if  we  keep 
our  eyes  firmly  on  the  task. 


PartIV 
RESPONSIBILITY  AND  ACCOUNTABILITY 


CHAPTER 

22 

Essentials  of  Responsibility 

1.  MEN  AND  INSTITUTIONS 

Responsibility  is  at  the  roots  of  civilization  and  government.  It  is  the 
derivative  of  centuries  of  human  experience.  It  is  based  on  the  best  in  He- 
brew-Greek-Christian thought  as  revived  and  reinterpreted  in  our  culture 
since  the  beginning  of  modern  times. 

Responsibility  is  a  characteristic  of  both  men  and  institutions.  Indeed, 
it  needs  to  permeate  men  and  institutions  alike  if  it  is  to  exist  at  all.  Respon- 
sible men  create  responsible  institutions,  and  responsible  institutions  develop 
responsibility  in  men. 

Responsible  Men.  The  concept  of  responsibility  is  ubiquitous.  It  is  not 
an  isolated  phenomenon  of  politics.  Responsibility  is  a  determining  factor 
in  the  character  of  property,  the  nature  of  the  family,  and  the  constitution 
of  the  state.  It  pervades  our  systems  of  ethics,  law,  politics,  and  religion.  It  is 
not  something  to  be  defined  in  a  neat  sentence — it  is  the  horizon  of  mankind." 

In  the  long  journey  toward  that  horizon,  however,  much  ground  has 
been  covered.  Some  of  the  landmarks  are  worth  noting.  Responsibility,  as 
we  know  it  today,  is  a  product  of  Western  civilization.  It  has  assumed  pro- 
gressively clearer  meaning  since  the  Renaissance  and  the  Reformation.  It  is  a 
matter  of  ideas,  ideals,  attitudes,  and  conscious  obligation.  It  is  also  a  matter 
of  custom,  convention,  and  law.  We  note  a  striking  geographical  coincidence 
between  the  development  of  cultural  individualism  and  that  of  institutions 
of  political  responsibility.  Representative  assemblies,  mayority  rule,  minority 
rights,  accountable  officials,  and  government  according  to  law  are  not  to 
be  found  except  where  a  high  value  is  placed  upon  man's  growth  for  his 
own  sake  and  where  men  generally,  more  than  a  mere  few,  have  come  to 
accept  responsibility. 

What  are  the  attributes  of  responsible  men?  We  may  name  some  of 
them.  First,  responsibility  cannot  exist  unless  there  is  capacity — in  the 
political  context,  authority— of  a  discretionary  character.  Children  once 
were  said,  perhaps  hopefully,  to  reach  "the  age  of  responsibility."  Helpless 

501 


502  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

infants  are  not  responsible.  Not  until  the  child's  powers  have  developed  is 
he  able  to  be  responsible,  or  irresponsible.  Before  that  time  the  concept  is 
inapplicable.  We  look  not  to  the  helpless  but  to  the  powerful  in  society 
to  play  a  responsible  role. 

Discretion  is  also  essential  to  responsibility,  which  is  something  more 
than  enforceable  accountability.  A  duty  that  contains  no  element  of  initiative, 
judgment,  or  choice  for  the  one  obliged  to  perform  it  may  be  a  matter 
of  accountability,  but  not  of  responsibility  in  the  wider  sense.  In  the  Parable 
of  the  Talents  the  servant  who  hid  his  talent  in  a  napkin  chose  to  meet  a 
standard  of  accountability — he  produced  the  talent  on  demand — when  in 
fact  he  knew  that  he  was  vested  with  discretion  and  that  he  was  expected 
to  exericse  his  initiative  in  pursuing  a  policy  of  investment. 

A  second  characteristic  of  responsible  men  is  recognition  of  an  obliga- 
tion to  meet  a  need  that  exceeds  the  individual's  and  to  act  according  to  a 
standard  that  is  outside  himself  and  beyond  his  control.  Such  recognition 
must  be  effective  even  though  it  may  not  necessarily  be  articulate.  A 
responsible  member  of  a  family  recognizes  at  least  some  family  interests 
as  superior  to  his  personal  interests.  A  member  of  a  political  party  recog- 
nizes certain  party  interests  as  being  above  his  own  interests.  A  responsible' 
public  official  recognizes  a  public  interest  as  overriding  any  interest  of  his 
own  or  the  interest  of  any  group  or  class  to  which  he  may  belong. 

The  standard  of  responsibility  is  perhaps  as  important  as  the  interest. 
Hitler's  action  in  attempting  to  destroy  Christianity  in  Germany  was  not  a 
simple  act  of  gratuitous  malevolence.  The  action  had  a  certain  logic  to  it. 
As  long  as  a  standard  of  conduct  existed  that  was  outside  his  control,  he 
might  be  held  responsible  in  terms  of  that  standard  in  the  minds  of  some. 
To  escape  completely  such  judgment,  he  was  driven  to  attempt  to  destroy 
the  independent  system  of  values.  The  existence  of  a  state  religion  in 
authoritarian  countries  is  no  mere  accident. 

A  third  characteristic  of  responsible  men  is  regard  for  consequences.  We 
say  that  an  automobile  driver  who  recklessly  endangers  his  life  and  the 
lives  of  others  drives  irresponsibly.  He  who  has  no  regard  for  truth  but 
makes  wild  statements  is  also  said  to  speak  irresponsibly.  A  political 
representative  who  votes  in  disregard  of  the  effect  of  his  decisions  acts 
irresponsibly. 

^^Responsibility  connotes  a  certain  amount  of  rationalism  and  an  element 
or  prudence.  A  responsible  leader  may  endanger  his  own  life  or  the  lives 
of  his  followers,  but  he  will  only  do  it  for  a  considered  reason,  after  some 
weighing  of  the  objectives  and  some  calculation  of  the  risks.  It  is  this 
element  of  responsibility  in  leadership  that  holds  a  group  together.  Men 
will  not  continue  to  support  a  program  that  an  irresponsible  leader  deprives 
of  promise  of  success. 

-^  Another  way  of  putting  it  is  that  responsibility  contains  a  time  perspec- 
tive of  more  than  the  moment.  The  future  is  as  important  as  the  present. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  503 

A  responsible  party  leader  does  not  jeopardize  the  welfare  of  his  party.  A 
responsible  official  does  not  endanger  the  security  of  the  state.  A  respon- 
sible administrator  does  not  imperil  the  vitality  of  his  organization.  V- 

Responsible  Institutions.  When  the  concept  of  responsibility  is  suffi- 
ciently strong  to  be  reflected  in  men's  lives,  it  is  also  to  be  found  in  the 
political  institutions  of  representative  government.  In  the  United  States  of 
America  we  take  these  institutions  for  granted,  and  have  forgotten  their 
origin.  Their  common  ancestry  is  worth  noting. 

All  may  be  traced  to  the  combined  influence  of  Christian  thought  and 
Greek  rationalism  reconsidered  in  the  perspective  of  Reformation  and 
Renaissance.  Majority  rule,  minority  rights,  and  individual  rights  rest 
squarely  upon  belief  in  the  value  of  the  individual  human  being,  upon  belief 
in  the  equal  value  of  human  beings.  In  the  light  of  reason,  justification 
of  majority  rule  is  a  simple  mathematical  process.  The  coexistence  of  major- 
ity rule  with  minority  rights  and  individual  rights  has  in  it  not  a  little 
gf  the  Grecian  ideal  of  moderation  and  restraint.  It  also  assumes  sufficient 
unity  and  generosity  to  permit  a  reconciliation  of  majority,  minority,  and 
individual  interests. 

In  the  development  of  discrete  institutions,  formal  procedures,  and 
known  rules  of  law  we  recognize  the  influence  of  rationalism.  Good  will 
is  not  enough.  The  problems  to  be  dealt  with  are  of  a  nature  and  volume 
to  require  concrete  machinery.  To  assure  responsible  results,  men  steeped  in 
Western  culture  have  not  been  content  to  rely  on  mysticism,  absolutism,  or 
chance.  With  the  rationalism  of  the  observational-clinical-laboratory  ap- 
proach, they  have  preferred  mechanics  as  a  means  of  increasing  the 
probability  that  responsible  men  will  govern  in  a  responsible  way. 

Interdependence  of  Men  and  Institutions.  Some  aspects  of  the  interde- 
pendence of  responsibility  in  men  and  in  institutions  may  be  seen  in  the 
family.  Marriage  is  a  responsible  institution  with  duties  and  obligations — 
some  of  them  established  by  laws.  But  it  also  gives  the  parties  to  the  union 
wide  discretion.  Administrative  supervision  ends  with  the  issuance  of  the 
marriage  license.  The  obligations  assumed  and  the  standards  accepted  by 
the  contracting  parties  are  stated  in  very  general  terms.  It  is  up  to  each  party 
jointly  to  recognize  and  determine  what  the  needs  of  the  family  require 
in  personal  terms  and  to  make  his  or  her  contribution  accordingly. 

Families  flourish  because  men  and  women  do  make  the  contribution 
needed.  It  is  frequently  much  greater  than  they  could  be  compelled  to  make, 
and  it  is  not  always  an  equal  contribution.  The  interests  of  the  family,  future 
as  well  as  present,  are  the  governing  considerations.  Responsible  men  and 
women  recognizing  such  needs,  accepting  obligations  to  meet  them,  and 
thinking  about  the  future  of  the  family  make  the  family  successful. 

The  traditions,  the  conventions,  the  social  sanctions,  and  the  laws  which 
surround  family  life  stimulate,  influence,  and  restrain  action.  They  outline 
the  pattern  and  help  to  secure  conformance  to  it.  Both  the  pattern  and  the 


504  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

sanctions  arc  essential.  We  must  add,  however,  that  they  are  not  sufficient 
alone.  Some  families  break  up  even  though  the  institution  of  marriage  in 
general  does  not  collapse.  Unless  there  is  generally  a  reasonable  development 
of  the  quality  of  responsibility  in  the  people  involved,  any  institution  is 
ineffective. 

The  position  of  the  child  in  the  family  also  emphasizes  the  relationship 
of  institutional  management  to  the  personal  quality  of  responsibility.  Rear- 
ing a  child  is  in  part  a  matter  of  developing  in  him  an  effective  sense  and 
habit  of  responsibility.  A  general  regime  is  set  up  for  the  child,  and  he  is 
instructed  about  things  to  be  done  and  things  not  to  be  done.  Both  father 
and  mother  try  to  hold  him  to  account  for  his  conduct. 

But  this  is  an  exhausting  and  time-consuming  process.  A  child's 
interests  and  energy  quickly  go  beyond  the  limits  of  any  scheme  of  de- 
tailed guidance.  The  parental  council  would  have  to  be  in  continuous 
session  to  prescribe,  proscribe,  and  prohibit;  and  more  supervision  than  is 
feasible  would  be  necessary.  Parents  cannot  stand  over  the  child  with  a 
stick  all  the  time  or  wash  behind  his  ears  all  his  life.  The  only  real  solu- 
tion for  child  as  well  as  parents  is  for  the  child  to  assume  increasing  re- 
sponsibility for  his  own  conduct — responsibility  that  involves  initiative, 
judgment,  restraint,  and  recognition  of  obligations. 

The  growth  of  responsibility  in  the  child  is  by  no  means  spontaneous. 
It  is  in  part  a  product  of  the  efforts  of  the  parents.  In  fact,  it  is  a  principal 
function  of  the  institution  of  family  life.  The  effort  required  to  develop 
responsibility  in  a  boy  or  girl  probably  varies  greatly;  but  even  the  mini- 
mum effort  is  colossal.  Success  is  the  crowning  achievement  of  the  home, 
bolstered  by  school  and  church.  An  active  system  of  expressing  account- 
ability is  essential  to  success,  but  unless  there  is  success  in  establishing  the 
ideals,  attitudes,  and  habits  of  responsibility,  the  home  has  failed. 

The  Political  Implications  of  Business  Practice.  Responsibility  is  taught 
explicitly  and  also  by  inference.  Specific  concepts  grip  men's  minds,  and 
the  implications  of  ways  of  living  are  equally  influential.  How  can  we  ex- 
plain the  change  in  political  responsibility  that  took  place  in  the  United 
States  during  the  nineteenth  century?  At  the  beginning  of  that  century,  as 
we  know,  the  leaders  of  society — that  is,  the  leaders  in  business,  agriculture, 
and  the  professions — were  also  the  political  leaders.  They  recognized  their 
problems  and  stepped  forward.  Many  of  them  devoted  their  thought,  their 
energy,  their  money,  and  their  lives  to  resolving  public  issues. 

These  leaders  were  broadly  active  in  public  affairs.  They  took  upon 
themselves  the  burden  of  political  discussion  and  decision.  By  the  end  of  the 
century,  the  situation  had  changed.  Some  businessmen  continued  to  be 
publicly  active  in  politics,  but  they  were  now  a  minority.  Most  business  lead- 
ers had  withdrawn  from  broad  political  responsibility.  The  professional  poli- 
tician had  appeared,  recognized  as  a  broker,  not  to  take  the  place  left  by  the 
natural  leaders  of  society,  but  to  substitute  for  them,  to  fill  the  vacuum. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  505 

Why  did  so  many  men  whose  ability,  achievements,  wealth,  and  pres- 
tige qualified  them  for  leadership  choose  not  to  exert  such  leadership?  There 
are  many  explanations,  of  course.  Among  them  was  the  important  influence 
of  the  pattern  of  business  itself.1  The  new  business  organizations  and  busi- 
ness practices  were  training  men  to  narrow  their  responsibility  as  much  as 
possible,  even  to  escape  responsibility  entirely. 

At  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  property  was  private  in  a 
personal  sense.  Business  property  was  private,  business  was  private.  A  man 
was  engaged  personally,  either  alone  or  with  his  partners,  in  a  business  en- 
terprise. He  was  personally  committed,  personally  accountable,  personally 
responsible  for  the  business  enterprise.  Joint  stock  companies  were  the 
exception.2  In  the  orthodox  view  their  usefulness  was  limited.  Charters 
were  a  special  privilege  conferred  by  special  legislative  act,  and  they  did 
not  necessarily  grant  limited  liability  to  corporate  owners.  Corporate 
purposes  were  narrowly  limited,  and  corporate  powers  were  narrowly 
construed. 

By  the  end  of  the  century  the  situation  in  the  United  States  had  com- 
pletely changed.  Businessmen  who  were  fully  responsible  in  their  person  and 
.property  for  all  their  actions  were  a  dead  or  dying  species/ Business  was 
corporate.  All  corporations  carried  the  privilege  of  limited  liability.  More- 
over, the  requirements  of  capital  investment  by  the  incorporators  had  been 
so  far  abandoned,  and  the  capital  structure  had  been  permitted  to  become 
so  complicated,  that  it  was  both  possible  and  proper  for  businessmen  to 
launch  and  operate  an  enterprise  without  any  true  personal  liability.  The 
restrictions  on  corporate  purposes  had  been  swept  away,  and  the  privilege 
of  incorporation  had  become  a  right. 

Business  had  ceased  to  be  private  in  any  real  sense,  but  it  had  certainly 
not  become  public.  It  was  characteristically  irresponsible.  Businessmen 
who  lived  and  worked  in  this  system  were  schooled  in  the  arts,  the  attitudes, 
and  the  habits  of  irresponsibility.  Through  the  corporate  charter  they  could 
secure  capital  with  a  negligible,  if  any,  investment  of  their  own.  They  could 
control  a  corporation  which  they  did  not  own.  They  contracted  for  land, 
materials,  and  labor;  and  these  contracts  could  either  be  lived  up  to  or 
repudiated  and  litigated.  The  system  of  minimizing  responsibility,  coupled 
with  the  vast  growth  in  size  of  business  units,  had  an  inevitably  debilitating 
effect  upon  the  quality  of  responsibility  in  the  natural  leaders  of  a  society 
which  was  becoming  increasingly  industrial  in  character. 

1This  explanation  of  certain  tendencies  toward  irresponsibility  in  American  politics  b 
offered  as  an  hypothesis. 

2  Cf.  Adam  Smith's  dictum  that  "The  only  trades  which  it  seems  possible  for  a  joint 
stock  company  to  carry  on  successfully,  without  an  exclusive  privilege,  are  those  of  which  all 
the  operations  arc  capable  of  being  reduced  to  what  is  called  a  routine,  or  of  such  a  uni- 
formity of  method  as  admits  of  little  or  no  variation.1*  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  V,  ch.  1, 
pt.  3,  art.  I,  "Of  Public  Works  and  Institutions  which  are  Necessary  for  Facilitating  Particu- 
lar Branches  of  Commerce." 


506  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

Automatism?  It  was  easy  to  transfer  these  attitudes  and  habits  of  mini- 
mizing responsibility  from  business  to  politics.  In  both  fields,  irresponsi- 
bility was  doubtless  fostered  by  the  prevailing  belief  in  the  automatic  quali- 
ties of  the  economic  and  political  order.  The  vulgar  version  of  the  doctrines 
of  the  classical  economists  seemed  to  encourage  each  entrepreneur  to  do  the 
best  he  could  for  himself  by  whatever  means  he  could  find.  Although 
the  competition  of  numerous  small  and  distinctly  private  business  units  had 
given  way  to  the  strife  of  corporate  combinations,  relatively  irresponsible 
in  character  and  ruthless  in  methods,  it  was  still  argued  that  the  aggregate 
of  this  total  effort  was  the  public  good.  It  was  still  assumed  that  there  was 
an  economic  "system"  which  could  stand  any  amount  of  pulling  and 
hauling. 

Similar  reliance  was  placed  upon  the  automatic  qualities  of  the  political 

order.   Representative  assemblies  were  firmly  established.   Almost  universal 

manhood  suffrage  had  been  achieved,  and  the  franchise  was  exercised 

through  a  long  ballot  at  frequent  elections.   It  was  felt  that  this  kind  of 

democracy  had  so  much  inherent  stability  that  any  number  of  people  could 

fock  the  boat  with  impunity,  and  that  the  efforts  of  special  interests  to 

secure  privileges   would  balance.    No  one  had  to  assume  responsibility 

for  operating  or  maintaining  the  ship  of  state. 

Darwin's  theory  of  evolution  and  the  popular  inferences  that  were  made 
from  it  no  doubt  encouraged  the  belief  in  social  automatism.  In  America, 
furthermore,  the  expanding  population,  the  exploitation  of  rich  resources, 
and  the  process  of  industrial  development  provided  what  seemed  to  be  tan- 
gible and  convincing  evidence  of  the  durability  of  "progress."  It  was  easy 
to  believe  in  a  scheme  which  did  not  require  any  one  in  particular  to  play 
a  responsible  part  in  public  affairs  and  which  made  it  unnecessary  to  worry 
about  the  social  consequence  of  individual  action. 

Two  world  wars  with  a  world-wide  depression  between  them  have  been 
a  tough  dish  for  mankind.  Who  now  really  thinks  that  the  world  order 
or  any  "system"  will  unguidedly  produce  either  peace  or  prosperity?  Who 
really  believes  in  the  automatism  of  any  stereotyped  concept  of  society? 

The  events  of  the  last  half  century  challenge  any  superstitious  belief 
in  social  automatism.  It  is  now  obvious  that  if  the  benefits  inherent  in 
world  culture  and  world  resources  are  to  be  realized,  it  is  necessary  to 
achieve  a  higher  level  of  responsibility  in  men  and  in  institutions  than 
society  has  yet  attained.  The  situation  demands  ability,  initiative,  and  dis- 
cretion, exercised  to  meet  the  needs  of  society  and  not  merely  the  needs 
of  an  individual,  a  class,  or  even  a  single  nation.  The  standards  by  which 
the  adequacy  of  policies  must  be  measured  have  risen.  The  consequences 
of  action  or  inaction  by  any  substantial  group  in  society  must  be  carefully 
considered.  Responsibility  is  at  an  extraordinary  premium  for  the  present 
and  the  future. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  507 

2.  LEGISLATIVE  RESPONSIBILITY 

In  this  chapter  we  are  concerned  particularly  with  political  responsibility, 
even  though  it  is  obviously  only  a  part  of  the  wider  phenomenon.  What  is 
the  responsibility  of  legislators?  Of  elected  executives?  Of  administrative 
officials?  We  will  forego  the  pleasure  of  talking  about  the  responsibility 
of  judges. 

Responsible  Legislators.  Responsible  government  is  impossible  without 
responsible  legislators  and  without  a  realistic  system  of  legislative  responsi- 
bility. The  essential  features  of  a  system  of  responsibility  are  generally 
agreed  upon  and  need  only  be  mentioned  here:  frequent  but  not  too- 
frequent  elections,  honest  elections,  an  adequate  number  of  representatives 
but  not  too  long  a  ballot,  reasonable  equality  in  representation  as  a  basis  for 
majority  rule,  and  so  on.  Although  the  advent  of  the  initiative,  referendum, 
and  recall  may  seem  to  complicate  the  system,  it  also  highlights  an  important 
aspect  of  all  responsible  institutions. 

Institutions  which  permit  responsible  political  action  necessarily  provide 
for  discretion,  and  discretion  admits  of  abuse.   If  the  ends  of  responsible 
government  are  to  be  achieved,  the  authorized  discretion  must  be  exercised 
with  due  regard  for  consequences,  must  be  guided  by  the  needs  of  the  com- 
munity, and  must  conform  at  the  very  minimum  to  the  ethical  and  moral 
standards  of  the  community.   The  usefulness  of  the  initiative  and  referen- 
dum depends  upon  the  restraint  and  the  judgment  with  which  they  are 
exercised. 

Persistent  and  irresponsible  special  interests  could  conceivably  weaken 
the  legislative  process  seriously  by  excessive  use  of  the  initiative.  Although 
a  highly  developed  sense  of  responsibility  in  the  electorate  would  check  and 
eventually  shut  off  such  tactics  of  pressure  groups,  the  system  of  direct  con- 
trol calls  for  a  sense  of  responsibility  among  special  interests  as  well  as  in 
the  general  public.  The  referendum,  too,  can  be  abused  by  excess.  With 
reasonable  restraint  in  application,  it  becomes  a  valuable  procedure  for  deal- 
ing with  extraordinary  situations.  The  recall  is  similarly  a  welcome  addi- 
tion to  the  scheme  of  responsibility  which  could  be,  but  generally  has  not 
been,  carried  to  extremes. 

Realism  in  Responsibility  of  Legislators.  The  demand  for  responsibility 
in  legislators  goes  much  further  than  is  indicated  by  electoral  devices. 
It  is  obvious  that  representative  government  is  a  farce  if  the  elections  are 
dishonest.  Honesty  in  elections,  however,  requires  a  great  deal  more  than 
counting  the  ballots  with  due  regard  for  mathematical  accuracy.  An  elec- 
tion can  perform  its  function  only  when  the  campaign  itself  is  reasonably 
honest.  If  the  candidates  for  election  disregard  the  truth  and  fill  the  air 
with  unfounded  assertions,  fantastic  charges,  and  malicious  misrepresenta' 
tions,  they  make  it  impossible  to  achieve  responsible  government  through 
the  electoral  process. 


508  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

The  need  for  honest  discussion  is  equally  great  within  the  legislative 
assembly.  Lawmaking  bodies  and  the  legislative  process  rest  on  the  founda- 
tion of  faith  in  reason.  Discussion  is  an  effective  means  of  getting  at  the 
facts  and  of  weighing  them  when  all  parties  to  the  discussion  act  in  good 
faith.  However,  unless  the  preponderant  purpose  of  the  legislators  is  to 
make  debate  a  rational  process,  the  issues  can  be  so  confused  with  half-truths 
or  untruths  as  to  render  discussion  ridiculous. 

<L  Majority  rule  is  obviously  a  cornerstone  of  responsible  government.  The 
legislative  process  is  intended  to  be  a  means  of  discovering  or  formulating  a 
majority  view,  and  a  legislative  decision  should  rest  upon  the  support  of 
the  majority.  Majority  rule  may  be  and  frequently  is  defeated,  however,  by 
irresponsible  legislators.  Dilatory  action  may  prevent  effective  discussion 
or  make  a  decision  impossible.  Committees  may  refuse  to  report  bills  upon 
which  a  majority  clearly  wishes  to  act. 

Although  legislative  rules  generally  permit  the  majority  to  compel  com- 
mittees to  act,  the  procedure  is  so  laborious  as  to  be  serviceable  only  in  rare 
instances.  A  committee  may  also  handle  its  hearings  and  taking  of  evidence 
in  such  an  arbitrary  and  biased  way  that  the  lawmaking  body  never  has 
a  chance  of  considering  the  proposed  measure  on  its  merits.  Committee 
members  who  are  governed  more  by  a  special  interest  than  by  the  general 
interest  may  destroy  responsible  government.  Can  a  legislative  chamber 
function  effectively  as  a  representative  body  when  the  committees  are  not 
fully  responsible  to  the  majority  of  the  chamber  ? 

Legislative  Irresponsibility?  The  British  government  is  sometimes  criti- 
cized on  the  grounds  that  the  Cabinet — conceived  as  a  committee — is  not  the 
servant  of  the  House  of  Commons,  but  has  become  its  master,  and  a  despotic 
master  at  that.  In  American  legislative  assemblies,  which  typically  work 
through  committees,  are  the  committees  fully  responsible  to  the  assembly  or 
have  they  become  arbitrary  and  irresponsible  rulers?  In  many  instances  they 
fall  short  of  any  reasonable  standard  of  responsibility. 

Let  us  consider  the  evidence,  starting  with  committee  hearings.  Is  the 
investigation  an  impartial  and  careful  inquiry  into  the  facts?  Too  fre- 
quently it  is  the  cross-examination  of  witnesses  by  a  hostile  prosecutor,  or 
the  staging  of  a  dramatic  scene  with  a  carefully  selected  professional  cast. 
When  we  consider  the  methods — not  to  mention  the  manners — of  many 
committees  of  Congress,  we  find  it  not  so  strange  that  civil  servants  cringe 
at  the  thought  of  "going  up  on  the  Hill,"  and  that  legislative-executive  rela- 
tions lack  cordiality.  The  "third  degree"  is  not  a  good  way  to  find  the 
truth  or  to  make  friends.  It  may  force  testimony  which  is  desired;  but  if 
the  victim  lives  and  is  interrogated  again  he  will  be  forever  after  on  guard. 

The  mysteries  of  a  committee's  deliberations  perhaps  defy  analysis,  but 
what  about  its  decisions?  One  of  the  committee's  functions  in  American 
practice  is  to  "screen"  legislation.  This  is  an  act  of  responsible  discretion. 
But  how  is  the  screening  done?  Is  it  a  rational  process  of  sifting  the  signifi- 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  509 

cant  from  the  trivial?  Is  it  guided  by  a  policy  based  on  views  of  the  major- 
ity of  the  committee?  If  there  is  a  general  policy,  does  it  have  the  support 
of  the  majority  of  the  legislative  chamber  or  does  it  represent  merely  the 
views  of  a  vested  legislative  interest?  And  if  there  is  no  guiding  policy, 
what  governs  the  screening  process?  Chance,  whim,  or  the  dictates  of 
the  chairman? 

How  many  sessions  of  Congress  pass  without  arbitrary  action  by  some 
standing  committee  or  by  the  Rules  Committee  to  prevent  discussion  and 
to  defeat  the  determination  of  a  policy  by  the  majority?  Not  many.  It  is 
no  defense  against  the  charge  of  irresponsibility  to  argue  that  not  a  few 
members  wish  to  be  relieved  of  the  necessity  of  confronting  embar- 
rassing issues.  The  evasion  of  responsibility  can  only  weaken  responsible 
government. 

Suicidal  Tendencies.  The  responsibility  with  which  a  legislative  chamber 
acts  is  the  product  in  part  of  the  way  in  which  it  is  constituted,  in  part  of 
the  character  of  its  members,  and  in  part  of  its  rules  and  organization.  The 
strength  of  the  seniority  principle  in  controlling  committee  assignments, 
committee  chairmanships,  and  positions  of  authority  in  the  chamber  is  a 
serious  cause  of  irresponsibility  in  American  government.  The  methods  by 
which  the  whole  house  can  hold  the  committee  to  account  for  its  action, 
or  inaction,  are  generally  inadequate. 

Gerrymandering,  whether  by  constitution  or  statute,  is  bad  enough  in 
most  legislatures.  When  the  lawmaking  body  by  its  rules  and  organization 
further  skews* the  representative  process  through  perpetuating  an  uncon- 
trolled oligarchy  of  unrepresentative  members,  it  allows  a  dangerous  sap- 
4>ing  of  its  own  vitality.  If  the  legislative  branch  is  suffering  a  decline,  as 
some  think,  the  danger  to  its  survival  is  not  to  be  sought  in  an  encroach- 
ment from  outside  by  the  executive  branch.  It  is  to  be  found  rather  in  the 
suicidal  tendencies  within  the  legislature  itself.  No  lawmaking  body  that 
violates  the  basic  principles  of  responsible  representation  can  hope  to  play 
anything  but  a  declining  role  in  grappling  with  the  complex  issues  which 
today  confront  government. 

Responsibility  and  Leadership.  Discussions  of  the  responsibility  of  legis- 
lators frequently  center  about  their  relations  to  their  constituents.  Should 
legislators  lead  or  follow?  If  they  lead,  how  far  ahead  should  they  lead? 
It  is  generally  agreed  that  voters  have  a  right  to  expect  their  representatives 
to  be  better  informed  and  more  farsighted  than  the  general  public.  Hence 
the  voter  can  without  embarrassment  change  his  mind  about  a  policy  as  he 
grows  wiser  through  experience.  The  legislator,  however,  is  supposed  to  be 
sufficiently  well  informed  that  he  makes  fewer  errors  and  foresees  develop- 
ments the  average  man  could  not  anticipate.  The  legislator's  foresight 
should  be  at  least  as  good  as  the  voter's  hindsight. 

The  relationship  between  the  representative  and  his  constituents  is  not 
a  matter  of  dealing  with  a  monolithic  mass  of  people.  In  even  the  most 


510  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

homogeneous  district  there  is  a  wide  variety  of  people  and  groups.  The 
number  of  purely  agricultural  districts — which  might  be  presumed  to  be 
most  homogeneous— is  dropping,  and  the  diversification  of  agriculture  is 
creating  a  variety  of  agricultural  interests.  Even  in  a  purely  agricultural 
district  living  off  a  single  crop,  interests  of  owners,  tenants,  laborers,  pri- 
mary processors  of  foods,  merchants,  and  bankers  have  to  be  considered. 
People  also  vary  in  race,  religion,  and  general^putlook  on  life.  In  urban 
districts  or  in  urban-rural  districts  the  variety  of  interests  is,  of  course,  very 
great. 

The  variety  of  interests  which  a  representative  must  consider  is  in 
one  sense  the  essence  of  his  problem,  but  it  also  provides  a  solution  to  the 
representative's  dilemma.  Some  interests  are  avid  and  well  organized.  If 
he  heeds  only  these,  he  may  become  their  slave.  Here  is  where  his  leader- 
ship can  come  to  the  fore.  If  he  has  not  sufficient  leadership  to  educate, 
organize,  and  appeal  to  the  broader  interests  of  his  district,  he  is  doomed  to 
be  the  servant  of  special  interests.  But  if  he  exercises  real  influence  he  may 
greatly  broaden  his  base  of  support  and  play  the  part  of  a  responsible 
leader  in  matters  of  public  policy. 

The  representative's  relationship  to  the  party  organization,  the  political 
machine,  or  the  "boss"  presents  a  similar  situation.  It  is  sometimes  said 
that  a  man  has  to  have  money,  organization  support,  or  both  to  be  nomi- 
nated and  elected.  It  may  be  readily  conceded  that  some  men  are  completely 
dependent  upon  money  or  the  machine  for  their  political  life,  but  it  does 
not  follow  that  every  one  is  so  dependent. 

A  political  "nobody"  naturally  cannot  become  a  Washington,  a  Jeffer- 
son, or  a  Roosevelt  by  simply  announcing  his  candidacy.  If  a  man  has 
qualities  of  leadership,  however,  if  he  has  the  ability  to  exercise  wise  judg- 
ment in  the  public  interest,  if  he  has  demonstrated  this  ability  in  previous 
activities,  he  will  have  a  reasonable  chance  of  being  elected  on  his  own 
merits.  When  a  political  "somebody"  comes  along  who  has  real  qualities 
of  leadership,  no  machine  and  no  amount  of  money  ordinarily  can  beat 
him.  The  opposition  also  has  to  put  up  a  strong  candidate.  When  a  candi- 
date says  that  "no  one"  can  be  elected  without  money  or  machine  support, 
look  him  over. 

This  is  not  to  say  that  money  and  the  political  machine  may  not  tip 
the  balance  or  even  defeat  the  interests  of  a  majority  of  the  people.  They 
often  do.  The  point  is  rather  that  real  leadership  of  a  responsible  character 
is  vital,  and  a  man  who  has  it  is  certain  to  be  able  to  play  a  useful  part 
in  politics.  He  may  not  always  win,  but  he  will  always  make  his  leadership 
felt  and  he  will  frequently  represent  the  public. 

Responsibility  of  the  Legislative  Body.  The  question  of  a  representative's 
relation  to  his  constituents  is  no  more  important  than  that  of  his  re- 
lation to  his  colleagues,  to  the  legislative  body  as  a  whole,  and  to  the 
general  public.  As  responsible  government  requires  a  man  in  authority  to 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  511 

look  beyond  himself,  his  group,  his  class,  and  his  party,  so  it  requires  him 
to  look  beyond  his  constituency  in  considering  public  needs.  His  obliga- 
tion to  the  total  public  overrides  his  obligation  to  any  part  of  it. 

Public  obligation  is  not  set  aside  by  a  federal  structure  of  government. 
The  right  of  secession  was  denied  in  our  constitutional  history  in  a  bloody 
Civil  War.  The  principle  of  the  higher  loyalty  to  the  broader  unity  is  fun- 
damental. The  obligation  is  legal  as  well  as  ethical.  But  how  can  it  be 
implemented? 

Any  representative  can  fulfill  the  obligation  for  himself.  Many  do  so. 
The  name  of  George  W.  Morris  will  long  be  remembered  as  that  of  a 
national  figure.  He  was  a  responsible  leader,  a  representative  whose  hori- 
zons and  constituency  were  as  broad  as  the  nation.  The  Tennessee  Valley 
Authority  was  not  built  in  Morris'  Nebraska. 

If  a  representative  will  not  meet  his  broader  obligations,  what  can  be 
done  about  it?  The  remedy  lies  with  his  colleagues  and  in  the  rules,  pro- 
cedures, and  organization  which  they  establish.  How  long  the  more  or  less 
disfranchised  rank  and  file  of  the  House  of  Representatives  will  stand 
for  being  pushed  around  by  the  venerable  oligarchs  who  rule  them  without 
representing  them,  no  one  knows.  But  they  don't  have  to  take  it  forever. 
The  rules  can  be  revised,  and  the  committee  system  can  be  changed.  The 
particularism  which  now  makes  both  House  and  Senate  a  playground  for 
special  interests  can  be  controlled. 

This  control  is  not  an  impossible  task.  It  is  not  inevitable,  for  example, 
that  committees  on  agriculture  should  be  in  the  hands  of  the  "farm  bloc." 
If  these  committees  contained  a  considerable  number  of  members  represent- 
ing areas  which  are  heavy  consumers  of  agricultural  products,  would  not 
the  committees  do  a  better  job  for  Congress,  for  the  public,  and,  in  the 
long  run,  for  the  farmers  ?  Reconciling  the  special  interest  with  the  general 
interest  should  begin  not  later  than  in  the  committee  stage. 

In  any  reconsideration  of  means  of  improving  the  legislative  process, 
it  is  essential  not  to  overlook  the  basic  importance  of  responsibility.  Many 
things  can  be  done  to  improve  and  expedite  the  work  of  Congress  and  state 
legislatures.  However,  unless  reforms  include  steps  to  strengthen  the  re- 
sponsible qualities  of  legislative  action  they  will  not  be  very  effective.  Rep- 
resentative committees  under  responsible,  not  dictatorial,  chairmen,  respon- 
sible to  the  entire  legislative  body  under  its  own  responsible  leaders,  could 
effect  a  revolution  in  the  quality  and  vitality  of  American  legislatures. 

Power  to  make  these  changes  rests  with  the  lawmaking  bodies  them- 
selves. The  present  leadership  is  opposed  to  change,  and  the  present  setup 
with  the  Inertia  JD£  many  years  behind  it  protects  them.  But  the  legislative 
rank  and  file  are  not  helpless.  Responsibility  carries  with  it  the  obligation 
to  use  granted  powers  only  for  the  public  good.  There  is  in  the  history 
jof  responsible  government  a  deep-seated  "right  of  revolution."  There  i§ 


512  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

also  a  positive  duty  to  revolt  against  any  abuse  of  discretion  or  authority 
which  obstructs  the  processes  and  the  ends  of  responsible  government. 

The  objection  may  be  raised  that  someone  will  get  hurt  in  the  course 
of  a  revolt  against  the  present  scheme  of  things.  To  be  sure,  someone 
will  get  hurt,  but  responsibility  carries  with  it  the  obligation  to  risk  some 
danger  and  to  make  some  personal  sacrifice  if  necessary.  Responsible  gov- 
ernment can  never  continue  very  long  unless  the  rank  and  file  as  well  as 
the  leaders  of  the  moment  show  qualities  of  responsibility,  and  unless  the 
former  establish  the  most  practical  means  possible  of  holding  the  latter 
responsible. 

3.   EXECUTIVE  RESPONSIBILITY 

Elected  Chief  Executives.  The  responsibility  of  legislators,  who  have  the 
broadest  authority  and  discretion  in  government,  should  properly  be  dis- 
cussed first.  Next  in  order  comes  that  of  the  elected  chief  executives,  such 
as  the  President  and  the  governors.3  They  are  participants  in  the  legislative 
process.  They  are  elected  representatives  of  the  public.  They  are  also  the 
chief  channels  through  which  the  experience  of  government  in  operation 
can  be  brought  together,  interpreted,  and  reintroduced  in  the  necessarily 
continuous  process  of  policy  formulation  and  administrative  improvement. 
The  elected  chief  executive  is  as  significant  an  American  contribution  to  the 
art  of  government  as  that  of  judicial  review. 

A  salient  feature  of  the  elected  chief  executive  is  the  breadth  of  respon- 
sibility which  attaches  to  his  office.4  There  has  been  public  insistence  and 
expectation  that  the  chief  executive  take  the  broad  view  of  public  policy; 
that  he  hold  the  balance  even  among  powerful  special  interests;  and  that 
he  subordinate  particular  interests  to  the  general  interest.  Presidents  are 
looked  to  for  leadership  in  the  entire  process  of  making  and  administering 
a  truly  national  policy;  and,  similarly,  governors  and  mayors  are  expected 
to  rise  above  any  special  interest. 

The  elected  chief  executive's  is  a  responsible  office  which  has  tended 

3  It  is  the  purpose  of  this  chapter  to  call  attention  to  some  of  the  more  obvious  charac- 
teristics of  responsibility  in  American  government  rather  than  to  treat  any  one  executive  or 
administrative  office  in  detail.     For  systematic  discussion  of  the  presidency  and  of  the  position 
of  state  governor,  see  such  works  as  Corwin,  Edward  S.,  The  President:  Office  and  Powers. 
New  York:  New  York  University  Press,  1940;  Berdahl,  Clarence  A.,  War  Powers  of  the  Execu- 
tive in  the  United  States,  Urbana:  University  of  Illinois,  1921;  Hart,  James  and  Spicer,  George 
W.,  "Executive  Leadership  in  Administration,"  pt.  II,  in  Essays  on  the  Law  and  Practice  of 
Governmental  Administration,  ed.  by  Hainfs,  Charles  G.  and  Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  Baltimore: 
Johns   Hopkins   Press,    1935;   Lipson,  Leslie,   The  American  Governor:  From  Figurehead  to 
Leader,  Chicago:  Chicago  University  Press,  1939.    Cf.  also  above  Ch.  8,  "The  Chief  Executive." 

4  All  responsibility  of  public  officials  is,  of  course,  responsibility  under  the  law,  within 
the  law,  and  in  accordance  with  the  law.    That  goes  without  saying  and  need  not  be  reit- 
erated throughout  our  discussion.   It  is,  however,  the  initiative  and  discretion  which  the  law — 
constitutional  and  statutory,   conventional   and  formal,  written  and  unwritten — gives  to  the 
public  official  that  makes  responsibility  a  subject  of  intrinsic  interest  and  importance. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  513 

to  develop  in  men  holding  it  a  sense  of  responsibility.  It  has  generally 
brought  out  the  best  in  presidents,  governors,  and  mayors.  The  tendency 
of  men  elected  to  it  to  rise  to  the  high  requirements  set  for  them  is  one  of 
the  most  encouraging  features  of  American  life.  This  tendency  may  also 
account  in  part  for  the  growth  in  political  power  and  prestige  which  our 
chief  executives  have  experienced.  Whatever  the  degree  of  change  in  the 
relative  standing  of  legislative  bodies  and  chief  executives,  it  has  certainly 
been  affected  by  the  different  ways  in  which  the  two  have  faced  up  to  the 
challenge  of  responsibility. 

Responsibility  of  the  Chief  Executive.  The  chief  executive's  responsibil- 
ity to  the  public  and  to  the  legislative  body  is  peculiarly  a  matter  of  integra- 
tion. He  must  take  the  lead  in  reconciling  conflicts  and  inconsistencies 
in  policy.  He  must  secure  some  synthesis  of  the  desires  of  his  total  con- 
stituency rfnd  the  total  experience  of  the  administrative  process.  His  respon- 
sibility to  the  public  and  the  legislature  also  largely  determines  the  nature 
of  his  responsibility  to  his  subordinates — his  administration. 

The  latter  responsibility  has  four  principal  features : 

(1)  The  chief  executive  must  give  his  subordinates  guidance  on  the 
general  direction  of  public  policy  and  the  timing  of  action. 

(2)  He  must  see  that  divergent  tendencies  within  the  administrative 
organization  are  reconciled  and  that  an  integrated  program  is  developed. 
Differences  of  personality  are  at  times  an  obvious  problem,  but  much  more 
fundamental  and  difficult  are  the  issues  of  policy. 

(3)  To  meet  these  needs,  he  must  be  in  touch  with  the  entire  adminis- 
tration and  he  must  utilize  its  experiences  and  advice.   That  is  to  say,  he 
has  an  obligation  to  his  subordinates  to  be  familiar  with  their  experience 
and  points  of  view  bearing  on  important  matters,  whether  or  not  he  acts 
upon  advice  they  give. 

(4)  He  must  also  see  that  there  is  an  adequate  pool  of  knowledge  and 
effective  cooperation  among  the  key  people  of  his  administration.     The 
pool  of  knowledge  must  be  greater  and  the  cooperation  more  extensive  than 
the  chief  executive's  own  knowledge  or  capacity  for  supervision. 

The  process  of  exchanging  information  of  mutual  interest  and  of  work- 
ing together  toward  an  over-all  program  and  its  consistent  administration 
must  go  on  throughout  all  levels  and  all  parts  of  the  executive  branch. 
For  the  chief  executive,  all  of  these  responsibilities  are  controls  in  organiz- 
ing and  managing  his  administration,  and  in  shaping  his  executive  office. 

The  chief  executive's  responsibility  for  guidance  on  broad  questions  of 
policy  is  obvious.  The  process  of  formulating  and  perfecting  public  policy 
is  partly  a  matter  of  reducing  alternatives  and  of  concentrating  upon  the 
more  promising  possibilities.  However,  for  the  most  effective  use  of  the 
resources  of  government  the  general  direction  must  be  determined.  There 
should  not  be  too  much  standing  around  at  the  crossroads.  If  these  decisions 


514  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

are  made  promptly,  public  officials  and  civil  servants  can  make  their  efforts 
count  most  effectively. 

It  may  at  times  be  desirable  to  advance  along  several  parallel  or  even 
slightly  divergent  routes.  Such  progress  requires  supervision  to  make  sure 
that  divergence  does  not  become  too  great  and  also  that  all  forces  converge 
upon  the  goal  at  the  right  time.  If  a  choice  between  completely  incon- 
sistent proposals  is  delayed  too  long,  either  much  of  the  subsequent  work 
is  bound  to  be  wasted  or  all  progress  is  certain  to  stop.  Neither  result  is 
desirable,  nor  is  the  accompanying  low  morale.  Of  course,  not  all  of  the 
chief  executive's  decisions  are  necessarily  difficult.  If  he  is  well  informed 
both  politically  and  administratively,  the  general  course  to  be  taken  may 
be  fairly  clear.  Even  on  the  most  difficult  questions,  however,  he  must  make 
up  his  mind  without  unreasonable  delay. 

Executive  Restraint.  How  much  responsibility  has  a  chief  executive  for 
initiating  policy  himself?  Obviously,  if  there  is  no  other  way  to  get  things 
started,  then  he  must  crank  the  engine  with  his  own  hand.  But  his  prime 
responsibility  is  to  see  that  sufficient  initiative  is  exercised  within  his  ad- 
ministration, rather  than  to  generate  all  the  ideas  himself.  Some  elected 
chief  executives  have  personally  identified  themselves  with  many  detailed 
policies  in  the  early  stages  of  development.  As  a  general  practice,  this  is 
probably  inconsistent  with  the  executive  function. 

In  the  game  of  government,  the  captain  of  the  administrative  team  is 
supposed  to  play  the  full  sixty  minutes.  If  he  runs  with  the  ball  on  every 
play  he  may  find  himself  completely  tuckered  out  before  the  end  of  the 
first  half,  and  he  cannot  be  very  effective  from  then  on.  For  example,  the 
President  is  not  only  a  legislative  leader,  and  the  leader  of  the  administra- 
tion, but  he  is  also  chief  of  state. 

There  is  a  certain  inconsistency  between  the  President's  several  roles, 
though  it  is  not  a  serious  problem  as  long  as  he  does  not  overplay  any  one 
part.  He  is  much  closer  to  his  essential  function  when  he  takes  public 
responsibility  for  reviewing  and  integrating  proposals  initiated  within  the 
administration  than  when  he  himself  proposes  and  promotes.  The  emphasis 
in  the  chief  executive's  responsibility  is  upon  integration. 

Executive  Emphasis  on  Teamworl^.  If  the  chief  executive  takes  his  re- 
sponsibility as  head  of  the  administration  seriously,  it  may  not  be  necessary 
for  him  to  make  so  many  public  decisions  of  a  controversial  character.  The 
best  time  to  integrate  policies  is  in  their  early  stages  of  development,  and 
Dn  the  lower  echelons  of  government.  As  Mary  Parker  Follett  so  well 
understood,  many  conflicts — social  as  well  as  administrative — are  unneces- 
sary, and  result  from  overlong  delayed  collaboration.5  They  are  also  the 
consequence  of  an  inadequate  pool  of  knowledge  and  of  too  limited 
perspective. 

5  For  a  cross-section  of  her  writings,  sec  Metcalf,  Henry  C.  and  Urwick,  L,,  eds.,  Dy- 
namic  Administration,  New  York:  Harper,  1942. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  513 

If  the  chief  executive  takes  a  lively  interest  in  assuring  that  people 
in  the  government  get  together  at  the  earliest  feasible  moment  on  matters 
of  common  importance,  he  tends  to  avoid  many  of  the  conflicts  which 
would  otherwise  harass  his  administration.  Of  course,  the  policy  of  hori- 
zontal, voluntary  coordination  should  be  facilitated  by  the  administrative 
structure  itself.  In  this  respect,  federal  administration  and  most  of  the 
state  governments  leave  much  to  be  desired.  No  better  device  has  so  far 
been  discovered  to  secure  cooperation  within  a  government  than  a  common 
superior  officer  who  insists  upon  cooperation.  There  are  too  many  pro- 
grams of  both  federal  and  state  governments  which  lack  any  effective 
common  superior. 

High  Official*— Political  Leadership.  The  highest  category  of  admin- 
istrative officials  includes  those  who  also  have,  by  the  nature  of  their  office 
and  duties,  political  responsibility.  A  typical  example  is  the  head  of  an 
executive  department.  He  stands  between  the  chief  executive  and  the 
lesser  administrative  officials  whose  positions  are  or  should  be  nonpolitical 
in  character.  That  pivotal  position  makes  his  office  of  peculiar  importance 
in  the  total  scheme  of  responsibility.  It  is  the  point  at  which  the  lay  control 
of  professional  administration  is  to  be  made  effective. 

To  handle  his  job,  the  department  head  needs  to  be  a  good  admin- 
istrator. But  it  is  «just  as  important — perhaps  even  more  important — that 
he  be  a  good  politician,  in  the  broadest  sense  of  the  word.  The  department 
head's  primary  responsibility  to  the  public,  to  the  chief  executive,  and  to 
his  subordinates  is  for  active  political  leadership.  As  we  have  noted,  the 
chief  executive  must  limit  himself  most  of  the  time  to  general  guidance, 
review,  and  integration  in  the  development  of  policy.  The  department  head, 
however,  has  no  obligation  to  continue  in  office  for  a  fixed  period.6  The 
measure  of  his  success  is  how  much  he  contributes,  rather  than  how  long 
he  lasts.  He  is  politically  expendable.  It  is  his  function  to  take  risks,  to 
^expose  himself  to  hostile  fire,  and  to  withdraw  or  be  carried  off  the  field 
when  he  has  performed  his  mission.  The  department  head  who  always 
plays  it  safe,  and  who  lets  his  chief  run  interference  for  him  rather  than 
get  into  the  interference  himself,  is  operating  on  the  wrong  level.  He 
should  apply  at  the  nearest  post  office  for  an  announcement  of  the  next 
civil  service  examinations  and  get  a  job  that  really  suits  him. 

When  the  chief  executive  is  a  strong  political  figure,  there  may  be  a 
tendency  for  his  subordinates  to  let  him  do  all  the  heavy  political  work. 
This  starts  a  wholly  undesirable  trend.  The  chief  executive  develops  more 
muscle  from  constant  exercise  and  his  lieutenants  get  weaker  from  lack  of 
it,  throwing  still  more  work  on  their  chief.  One  answer  is  for  the  depart- 
ment heads  to  face  up  to  their  political  responsibilities  even  if  they  have 

6  The  positions  of  elected  department  heads,  which  exist  in  many  state  governments, 
would  be  an  exception  to  this  rule.  On  the  appointive  department  head,  see  also  above  Ch. 
9,  "The  Departmental  System." 


516  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

to  risk  their  office  by  doing  so.    There  ought  to  be  a  law  against  cabinet 
members  owning  real  estate  in  or  near  the  District  of  Columbia. 

4.  ADMINISTRATIVE  IMPLICATIONS 

Politician  and  Civil  Servant.  Another  phase  of  a  department  head's  role 
is  to  take  full  responsibility  for  the  acts  of  his  subordinates.  This  does  not 
apply,  of  course,  to  those  of  his  associates  who  share  with  him  a  personal 
political  function.  Above  all,  he  must  always  protect  the  civil  servants 
from  political  pressures.  He  is  free  to  disregard  the  advice  of  his  pro- 
fessional staff.  He  may  modify  their  proposals,  or  overrule  them  entirely. 
But  he  should  never  allow  political  pressures  to  get  past  him  to  the  per- 
manent personnel,  i/ If  a  political  head  of  a  department  cannot  or  will  not 
take  public  responsibility  for  the  work  of  his  organization,  he  is  not  big 
enough  for  his  job. 

General  Interest  Versus  Special  Interest.  A  further  aspect  of  the  respon- 
sibility of  officials  who  are  immediately  subordinate  to  the  chief  executive 
is  their  common  obligation  to  work  together  in  the  development  and  ad- 
ministration of  a  coordinated  program.7  This  is  reciprocal  to  the  chief 
executive's  obligation  to  secure  teamwork  in  his  official  family.  It  calls  for 
a  nice  balancing  of  obligations.  As  the  head  of  a  department  the  adminis- 
trator is  responsible  for  the  development  and  management  of  his  depart- 
ment's program.  He  must  see  that  the  needs  of  the  program  receive  ade- 
quate attention,  and  that  the  full  implications  of  the  operating  experience 
are  available  in  the  revision  and  further  development  of  the  program. 

This  function  not  infrequently  makes  the  political  head  of  the  depart- 
mental organization  a  spokesman  for  a  particular  interest  of — or  in — the 
government.  He  speaks  for  agriculture,  or  labor,  or  the  Navy.  It  is  thus 
easy  for  him  to  forget  or  minimize  his  still  greater  obligation  to  see  that 
his  particular  program  is  developed  and  administered  in  accordance  with 
the  broadest  interests  of  the  government,  and  as  a  part  of  its  total  program. 
Balancing  the  particular  and  the  general  requires  fine  discrimination  and  a 
high  sense  of  responsibility. 

Although  the  chief  executive  is  responsible  for  making  certain  that  the 
essential  teamwork  occurs  among  all  agencies,  he  is  to  some  extent  at  the 
mercy  of  his  subordinates,  notwithstanding  his  possession  of  the  ultimate 
sanction  of  removal.  He  can  punish  public  quarreling,  but  it  is  more  diffi- 
cult to  prevent  his  desk  from  being  loaded  with  conflicts  which  need  never 
have  arisen.  A*d  if  subordinates  involved  in  a  conflict  of  policy  go  through 
the  motions  of  collaboration  but  never  progress  toward  common  ground, 
how  can  the  chief  executive  tell  whether  one  of  them  is  recalcitrant  or  all 
of  them  are  simply  standing  pat  ? 

T  One  of  the  best  discussions  of  the  essential  role  of  the  key  administrator  is  to  be  found 
in  Appleby,  Paul  H.,  Big  Democracy,  esp.  chs.  4,  7-9,  New  York:  Knopf,  1945. 


ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY  517 

Among  the  more  painful  difficulties  of  our  recent  wartime  administration 
were  certain  top  officials  who  were  uncritical  and  unrestrained  advocates 
of  the  worthiest  causes.  They  were  quite  unwilling  to  try  to  find  means  of 
achieving  their  ends  which  would  be  reconcilable  with  other  equally  im- 
portant objectives.  They  meant  well  but  they  created  more  problems  than 
enemy  saboteurs.8 

Integrity  and  Good  Faith.  Certain  responsibilities  of  political  officials 
are  duplicated  at  lower  levels  of  the  administrative  hierarchy.  Cross  co- 
ordination is,  of  course,  a  responsibility  at  all  echelons.  Each  key  man  has 
an  obligation  to  keep  his  group  posted  on  major  developments  or  informa- 
tion that  will  make  their  work  more  intelligent.  Similarly  each  has  an 
obligation  to  bring  to  the  attention  of  his  superior  all  the  facts  or  consid- 
erations which  the  latter  will  need  later  to  make  the  most  intelligent 
decisions  possible  or  to  take  the  action  that  may  be  required.9 

"The  truth,  the  whole  truth,  and  nothing  but  the  truth"  so  long  as  it  is 
relevant  probably  sums  up  an  administrative  official's  responsibility  to  his 
boss  for  information  and  advice.  Summarization  is  necessary,  of  course, 
but  it  must  be  accurate  condensation.  In  handling  questions  of  policy  an 
executive  is  dependent  on  his  staff  for  advising  him  honestly  and  fully. 
The  integrity  of  the  entire  organization  depends  upon  their  good  faith  in 
the  discharge  of  this  function.  Mistakes  and  errors  can  be  forgiven,  but 
lack  of  good  faith  is  inexcusable.  \J 

A  corollary  of  integrity  and  good  faith  in  dealing  with  the  one  to  whom 
an  administrative  official  is  responsible  is  effective  supervision  in  dealing 
with  those  for  whom  he  is  responsible.  A  large  element  in  effective  supervi- 
sion is  real  contact.  There  must  be  a  meeting  of  minds.  There  must  be 
mutual  confidence  and  understanding.  When  contact  is  lost  either  through 
infrequent  association  or  loss  of  confidence  and  understanding,  there  is 
danger  of  arbitrary  administration. 

An  official  may  not  always  be  able  to  put  his  mind  to  the  merits  of  every 
issue  that  comes  before  him.  But  he  must  be  sure  that  someone  whom  he 
has  tested  and  proved  to  be  competent  has  put  his  mind  to  every  issue. 
This  assurance  has  to  be  kept  current.  The  head  of  an  office  can  lose  con- 
tact at  times  with  some  of  the  business  flowing  through  it,  but  he  dare  not 
lose  contact  with  the  men  who  handle  that  business. 

Civil  Service— But  Not  Servility.  A  subordinate's  responsibility  includes 
the  obligation  to  tell  his  boss  things  which  the  latter  may  not  want  to  hear. 
But  how  far  does  the  obligation  go  ?  You  can  wear  out  your  welcome,  and 
"vain  repetitions"  get  you  nowhere.  Some  judgment  is  required  on  how 
hard  to  press  an  unpleasant  issue.  One  guide  is  the  importance  of  the  issue. 
If  the  matter  is  of  some  possible  consequence,  even  the  most  timorous  soul 
must  take  himself  in  hand  and  make  at  least  one  serious  effort  to  see  that 


8  Cf.  also  above  Ch.  14,  "Interest  Groups  in  Administration." 

9  See  also  above  Ch.  16,  "The  Formulation  of  Administrative  Policy/* 


518  ESSENTIALS  OF  RESPONSIBILITY 

his  superior  is  adequately  informed.  The  fact  that  his  responsibility  is  ad- 
ministrative rather  than  "political"  in  character  does  not  give  a  civil  servant 
the  right  to  be  a  Caspar  Milquetoast.10  vX 

The  scope  of  initiative  and  discretion,  of  course,  declines  as  we  go  down 
the  administrative  ladder.  Responsibilities  become  duties.  Accountability, 
not  responsibility,  governs.11  This  transition,  however,  is  not  uniform.  Many 
civil  servants  far  below  the  level  of  political  responsibility  have  positions  in 
which  they  may  and  must  exert  considerable  influence  upon  policy  and 
upon  the  administration  of  programs.12  They  have  positions  of  a  highly 
responsible  character  even  though  their  responsibility  is  within  the  admin- 
istrative family  and  not  to  the  public  or  the  legislative  body  directly.  It  is 
upon  their  integrity  and  their  devotion  to  the  loftiest  traditions  of  respon- 
sible government  that  much  of  the  success  of  modern  administration  must 
rest. 


10  The   literature   on   administrative   responsibility   proper  is   still  limited   in   scope.    Ref- 
erence may  be  made  to  the  following  writings:  Gaus,  John  M.,  "The  Responsibility  of  Public 
Administration,"  ch.  3,  in  Gaus,  John  M.  and  Others,  The  Frontiers  of  Public  Administration, 
Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,   1936;  Dykstra,  Clarence  A.,   "The  Quest  for  Respon- 
sibility,"   American   Political  Science   Review,    1939,   Vol.   33,   p.    1   ff.\   White,   Leonard   D., 
Introduction  to  the  Study  of  Public  Administration,  p.  561  #.,  New  York:  Macmillan,  2d  cd., 
1939;  Fricdrich,  Carl  J.,  "Public  Policy  and  the  Nature  of  Administrative  Responsibility,"  p. 
3  ff.,  in  Friedrich,  Carl  J.  and  Mason,  Edward  S.,  eds.,  Public  Policy,  Cambridge:  Harvard 
University  Press,    1940;  Morstcin  Marx,  Fritz,   "Administrative  Responsibility,"  p.  218  ff.f  in 
Morstein  Marx,   Fritz,  cd.,  Public  Management  in  the  New  Democracy,  New  York:  Harper, 
1940;    Finer,    Herman,    "Administrative    Responsibility    in   Democratic    Government,'*    Public 
Administration  Review,  1941,  Vol.   1,  p.  335  ft.\  Key,  V.  O.,  "Politics  and  Administration," 
p.  159  ft.,  in,  White,  Leonard  D.,  ed.,  The  Future  of  Government  in  the  United  States,  Chi- 
cago: University  of  Chicago  Press,  1942. 

11  The  transitional  area  is  surveyed  in  greater  detail  in  the  succeeding  chapters  of  this 
book. 

12  This  point  has  been  fully  developed  above  in  Ch.  4,  "Democratic  Administration." 


CHAPTER 


The  Judicial  Test 


1.   THE  RULE  OF  PRACTICALITY 

Propriety  of  Administrative  Rule-Making  and  Adjudication.  One  of 
the  surest  ways  to  obscure  the  workings  of  American  government  is  to 
insist  on  some  facile  generalization  like  "the  legislature  enacts  general  prin- 
ciples, the  courts  interpret  them,  and  the  executive  branch  administers 
them."  The  theory  of  the  separation  of  powers  was  never  fully  applied  to 
any  government  in  the  United  States — federal,  state,  or  local.  Yet  it  has 
misled  many  people  into  believing  that  it  is  somehow  improper  for  an  execu- 
tive agency  to  issue  regulations  or  to  judge  cases  affecting  private  rights. 

Before  we  discuss  the  way  in  which  public  administration  enters  into  the 
formulation  of  general  rules  and  the  adjudication  of  cases,  subject  in  both 
respects  to  review  by  the  courts,  one  elementary  fact  about  our  governmental 
system  should  be  noted.  On  each  level  of  government,  the  legislature 
generally  acts  only  as  a  single  body,  the  judiciary  handles  all  sorts  of  cases 
without  specializing  very  much  on  defined  categories,  but  the  executive 
branch  is  divided  into  departments  and  bureaus  each  of  which  does  a  par- 
ticular kind  of  work. 

Specifically,  when  an  issue  comes  to  a  legislative  decision,  every  member 
of  the  lawmaking  body  has  an  equal  vote  with  every  other  member  on 
every  type  of  question,  irrespective  of  his  individual  range  of  pertinent 
information.  Moreover,  because  of  the  sheer  quantity  of  business,  the  legis- 
lature cannot  undertake  to  prescribe  in  detail  all  the  rules  and  regulations 
that  need  to  be  issued  to  give  effect  to  the  decision  it  has  reached.  Similarly, 
the  courts  hear  cases  involving  all  kinds  of  legal  situations  arising  in  all  walks 
of  life.  Although  the  judicial  branch  may  have  any  number  of  inferior  courts, 
it  is  fundamentally  not  organized  to  decide  a  large  volume  of  particular 
categories  of  specialized  cases  promptly,  cheaply,  and  uniformly.  Only  by 
appropriate  organization  and  specialization  can  the  bulk  and  variety  of  gov- 
ernment business  be  handled  effectively. 

The  legislature  decides  the  most  important  questions  by  statutes  and  by 

519 


520  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

voting  appropriations,  but  beyond  the  general  disposition  of  the  matter  it 
must  rely  on  executive  officials  to  make  the  detailed  decisions.  At  this  point 
there  is  still  a  tremendous  quantity  of  rules  to  be  issued  to  implement  the 
statutes  and  interpret  their  meaning.  Similarly,  each  day  in  the  process 
of  administration  questions  come  up  that  involve  private  rights.  Admin- 
istrative officers  must  decide  most  of  these  questions;  partly  because  they 
can  decide  them  quicker,  cheaper,  and  more  generally  to  the  satisfaction  of 
the  public  than  any  one  else;  and  partly  because  the  judiciary  is  better 
equipped  for  the  decision  of  cases  involving  broad  principles  of  official 
conduct  and  public-law  relations. 

In  short,  the  functions  of  issuing  rules  and  deciding  cases  are  by  no 
means  exclusively  legislative  and  judicial.  Executive  agencies  must  dis- 
charge them  in  the  normal  course  of  business.  By  doing  so  they  manage, 
in  a  general  sense,  wide  areas  of  our  social  and  economic  system.  Since 
this  chapter  deals  particularly  with  the  administrative  processes  of  issuing 
regulations  and  adjudicating  cases,  and  with  court  review  of  these  processes 
as  well,  it  should  be  remarked  at  the  beginning  that  it  is  quite  normal  for 
the  quantity  of  administrative  regulations  to  exceed  the  quantity  of  statutes, 
and  for  a  great  many  more  cases  to  be  decided  by  administrative  agencies 
than  by  the  courts.  It  has  never  been  the  function  of  the  judiciary  to  pass 
automatically  on  all  regulations,  or  to  reconsider  all  aspects  of  every  ad- 
ministrative decision  whenever  a  citizen  believes  that  his  interests  have  been 
affected  by  a  government  agency. 

Test  of  Social  Utility.  Then  what,  in  those  respects,  is  the  judiciary's 
function,  and  who  decides  what  its  function  is  ?  The  latter  question  should 
be  answered  first.  The  legislature  by  statute  says  how  much  rule-making 
power  it  wants  to  delegate  to  executive  agencies,  and  also  fixes  the  boundary 
between  the  process  of  administrative  adjudication  and  the  judicial  function. 
The  courts  apply  the  Constitution  and  the  statutes  to  these  problems,  and — 
subject  to  the  guidance  of  law — may  have  the  last  word.  The  executive 
branch,  whatever  its  political  influence,  has  no  authoritative  voice  in  decid- 
ing how  far  its  power  runs. 

A  legislature  may  require  specific  types  of  administrative  rules  or  de- 
cisions to  be  reviewed  in  every  respect  by  the  courts,  and  it  sometimes  does. 
A  court  may  review  a  case  or  a  regulation  with  so  little  respect  for  the 
original  decision  of  an  administrative  agency  that  it  usurps  the  agency's 
function,  and  this  it  too  often  does.  In  either  case,  the  administrative  agency 
has  no  protection,  except  the  fact  that  in  the  long  run  the  increasing  in- 
terdependence in  society  and  the  resulting  expansion  of  governmental  func- 
tions in  themselves  will  convince  the  public  of  the  need  for  flexible  and 
specialized  management  that  administrative  organization  alone  can  provide. 

Only  by  administrative  organization  and  management  can  we  supply 
the  initiative,  the  expertness,  and  the  planned  teamwork  that  are  required  to 
solve  modern  problems.  The  way  in  which  executive  agencies  should  or- 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  521 

ganize  their  system  of  issuing  regulations  and  deciding  cases,  and  the  line 
between  their  function  and  that  of  the  judiciary,  are  matters  to  be  settled 
not  by  automatic  formulas  or  political  slogans,  but  by  the  practical  test  of 
social  utility. 

Two  Illustrations.  Let  us  consider  one  or  two  examples  to  illustrate  the 
point.  The  Post  Office  Department  will  carry  an  ordinary  letter  if  the 
sender  puts  a  three-cent  stamp  on  it,  and  it  will  carry  a  periodical  at  a  re- 
duced rate  if  the  sender  qualifies  for  second-class  mailing  privileges.  If  a 
letter  has  not  been  properly  stamped,  it  is  only  sensible  to  have  the  postal 
clerk  return  it  to  the  sender  for  postage,  or  put  a  postage-due  stamp  on  it 
and  collect  from  the  addressee,  according  to  the  instructions  the  clerk  gets 
from  his  department.  However,  the  question  of  second-class  mailing  privi- 
leges, though  hardly  different  in  principle,  is  a  question  of  vital  concern 
to  considerable  economic  interests,  and  the  statutes  say  that  a  publisher 
must  have  a  formal  hearing  before  the  Post  Office  Department  can  take 
those  privileges  away  from  him. 

In  both  types  of  transactions  the  Post  Office  Department  is  performing 
the  same  service.  In  principle,  there  is  no  reason  why  a  statute  should  not 
provide  for  a  formal  hearing  whenever  a  postal  clerk  and  a  private  citizen 
disagree  over  the  weight  of  a  letter.  In  practice,  there  is  a  perfectly  good 
reason.  People  want  their  mail  delivered,  and  realize  that  it  would  not 
make  sense  to  encourage  contentious  proceedings  that  would  hamper  the 
service.  Therefore,  the  less  important  question,  and  the  question  that  can 
more  easily  be  answered  according  to  a  definite  standard,  is  entrusted  to  the 
discretion  of  an  administrative  subordinate,  while  the  more  important  ques- 
tion of  second-class  mailing  privileges  is  the  subject  of  more  formal  pro- 
cedure at  a  higher  administrative  level— and,  if  necessary,  before  a  court 
of  law. 

For  another  example  we  might  turn  to  the  creation  of  an  army.  In  the 
eighteenth  century,  the  nation  relied  to  a  considerable  extent  on  legislative 
and  judicial  machinery  to  do  this  job.  The  Militia  Act  of  1792  (1  Stat.  271) 
provided  that  all  men  be  enrolled  in  the  militia,  and  enjoined  them  to  pro- 
vide themselves  with  muskets  and  with  musket-balls  one-eighteenth  of  a 
pound  in  weight.  Citizens  who  provided  themselves  with  such  arms  were, 
the  statute  said,  to  "hold  the  same  exempted  from  all  suits,  distresses,  exe- 
cutions or  sales,  for  debt  or  for  the  payment  of  taxes."  The  lack  of  neces- 
sary administrative  machinery  recommended  by  President  Washington  but 
neglected  by  Congress  made  this  system  a  fiasco,  as  the  War  of  1812 
demonstrated. 

The  mid-nineteenth  century  system — during  the  Civil  War— was  a 
centralized  system  of  conscription  administered  directly  by  the  Army.  The 
citizen  could  appeal  only  to  the  ordinary  courts.  The  drafting  of  men  dur- 
ing the  Civil  War  was  both  scandalously  arbitrary  and  inefficient. 


522  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

In  the  twentieth  century,  we  have  done  better  by  applying  two  related 
concepts:  the  creation  of  an  organization — the  Selective  Service  system — 
by  cooperative  arrangements  among  different  levels  of  government,  and 
the  issuance  of  rules  and  the  adjudication  of  individual  cases  by  that  or- 
ganization. It  would  be  hard  to  imagine  how  bad  a  system  Selective 
Service  would  be  if  the  functions  of  administration  and  adjudication  were 
separated.  If  the  Army  itself  drafted  men,  and  the  ordinary  courts  were  the 
only  place  in  which  to  get  a  hearing,  the  drafted  men  and  their  families 
would  certainly  consider  themselves  less  fairly  treated. 

Extending  the  Rule  of  Law.  In  these  two  examples — the  postal  system 
and  the  armed  forces — it  is  especially  obvious  that  the  process  of  adminis- 
trative regulation  and  adjudication  is  not  a  perversion  of  the  ordinary 
legislative  and  judicial  methods,  or  a  usurpation  by  executive  agencies 
of  functions  ordinarily  belonging  to  the  legislature  and  the  courts.  On  the 
contrary,  it  is  simply  a  means  by  which  an  executive  agency — either  on  its 
own  initiative  or  in  accordance  with  legislation — takes  systematic  precau- 
tions to  safeguard  private  rights.  As  one  authoritative  study  put  it,  the 
formal  procedure  of  administrative  rule-making  and  adjudication,  "far 
from  being  an  encroachment  upon  the  rule  of  law,  is  an  extension  of  it."1 
Administrative  adjudication  in  agencies  like  the  Federal  Security  Agency  and 
the  Veterans  Administration  has  a  similar  purpose—to  make  sure  that  gov- 
ernmental services  or  benefits  are  distributed  fairly,  which  is  a  matter 
somewhat  different  from  the  determination  of  rights. 

While  administrative  rule-making  and  adjudication  are  added  safeguards 
to  fair  play  in  the  administration  of  some  governmental  services,  they  are 
a  major  part  of  the  business  of  regulating  private  interests.  Some  activities 
which  need  to  be  controlled  in  the  public  interest  are  operated  under  systems 
of  government  ownership  or  management;  others  are  in  private  ownership 
and  subject  to  government  regulation.  Thus  regulation,  with  its  admin- 
istrative rule-making  and  adjudication,  is  an  alternative  to  public  ownership 
or  direct  public  control. 

Administrative  Regulation  as  Alternative  to  Public  Ownership.  The 
nation  might  have  considered  authorizing  the  federal  government  to  take 
over  the  railroads,  if  it  could  not  have  regulated  them  through  the  Inter- 
state Commerce  Commission;  or  the  shipping  lines,  if  it  were  not  for  the 
United  States  Maritime  Commission;  or  the  radio  networks,  but  for  the 
Federal  Communications  Commission;  or  the  banking  and  exchange  system, 
but  for  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  the  Federal  Home  Loan  Bank  System, 
the  Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  and  other  agencies.  Some  of 
these  are  primarily  agencies  which  handle  cases  by  direct  executive  action- 
die  Home  Owners  Loan  Corporation  did  not  hold  hearings  before  making  a 

1  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure,  Final  Report,  p.  12,  Senate 
Doc.  No.  8,  77th  Cong.,  1st.  Sess.,  Washington,  1941. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  523 

loan.  Others  are  primarily  regulatory  agencies  with  highly  developed 
processes  of  adjudication.  In  most  of  them,  however,  the  functions  of  ad- 
ministration and  adjudication  are  inseparable. 

It  is  at  least  partly  an  historical  accident  that  in  the  United  States  the 
federal  government  operates  the  postal  service  but  not  the  telephone  and 
telegraph  systems;  or  that  state  governments  operate  certain  hospitals  and 
sanatoriums  and  not  others;  or  that  municipalities  own  airports  but  not 
railroad  stations,  or  operate  one  utility — from  abattoirs  to  waterworks — 
and  leave  another  in  private  ownership.  What  may  start  as  an  historical 
accident  usually  becomes  a  firmly  rooted  tradition.  Podunk  is  shocked  to 
learn  that  Middletown  is  socialistic  enough  to  own  its  electric-power  plant, 
while  Middletown  is  surprised  to  discover  that  Podunk  violates  American 
tradition  by  getting  some  of  its  beef  from  a  municipal  slaughterhouse.  In 
much  the  same  way  Americans  are  generally  surprised  to  learn  that  the 
British  Post  Office  Department  handles  telegrams,  while  the  British  find  it 
hard  to  understand  that  even  well-to-do  Americans  may  be  educated  from 
kindergarten  to  Ph.D.  in  government  institutions. 

When  government  undertakes  to  regulate  great  corporations  instead 
of  taking  them  over,  it  has  two  general  alternatives,  or  a  mixture  of  both. 
One  is  to  proceed  by  first  laying  down  statutory  definitions  of  the  standards 
which  the  corporations  must  follow,  then  by  having  an  executive  agency 
investigate  their  operations,  and  finally  by  having  any  violations  prosecuted 
before  the  courts.  The  other  alternative  is  to  give  an  executive  agency 
authority  to  issue  detailed  regulations,  to  conduct  the  necessary  investiga- 
tions, and  to  hear  any  cases  involving  violations. 

The  latter  alternative  has  been  followed,  not  because  government  agen- 
cies grasped  for  power,  but  because  the  regulated  interests  greatly  preferred 
it.  A  private  corporation,  like  a  government  department,  cannot  operate 
if  many  of  its  decisions  are  likely  to  be  litigated.  If  it  has  to  be  regulated, 
it  would  rather  be  regulated  by  having  an  administrative  agency  enter  into 
a  sort  of  operating  partnership  with  it  and  take  over  certain  defined  con- 
trols, instead  of  having  a  prosecuting  attorney  dogging  its  footsteps. 

This  preference  may  be  a  surprise  to  the  casual  observer  who  takes  the 
complaints  of  businessmen  about  government  regulation  to  mean  that  they 
would  rather  be  prosecuted  in  a  court  than  regulated  under  an  administra- 
tive procedure.  As  one  Senator  has  put  it,  "One  of  the  great  difficulties  of 
the  Congress  in  attempting  to  avoid  the  detailed  regulation  of  business,  with 
indefinite  power  in  a  federal  bureau,  is  the  fact  that  in  many  cases  the  busi- 
nessmen themselves  seem  to  want  that  kind  of  regulation."2 

2.  THE  ADMINISTRATIVE  PROCESS  AND  THE  LAWYERS 

Prevention  Over  Punishment.  If  we  look  in  some  detail  at  the  methods 
of  government  regulation,  we  may  see  how  much  they  are  like  the  manage- 

2  Congressional  Record,  Vol.  86,  p.  10070  (August  8,  1940). 


524  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

ment  of  a  broad  field  of  activity  by  a  corporation,  and  how  much  they  have 
in  common  with  those  methods  that  are  essential  to  the  conduct  of  public 
administration  in  general.  As  with  all  types  of  administrative  actions, 
one  main  way  in  which  the  work  of  regulatory  agencies  differs  from  that 
of  the  judiciary  is  that  in  the  main  they  try  to  prevent  mistakes  rather  than 
punish  offenders.  The  courts  themselves,  of  course,  by  injunctions  and  man- 
damus proceedings  may  prevent  specific  injuries  and  compel  specific  actions, 
and  on  the  other  hand  administrative  agencies  may  punish  individuals  or 
corporations  for  offenses.  But  the  basic  distinction  still  holds  good. 

A  municipal  building-inspection  department  does  not  wait  to  take  steps 
against  a  landlord  until  the  elevator  collapses  and  kills  some  passengers;  it 
inspects  and  certificates  elevators  to  make  sure  they  are  safe.  The  Civil 
Aeronautics  Authority  does  not  merely  wait  to  prosecute  airplane  pilots  who 
through  incompetence  smash  their  planes;  in  a  more  practical  fashion  it 
examines  and  licenses  those  who  present  themselves  as  competent.  The 
Federal  Deposit  Insurance  Corporation  does  not  merely  adjust  its  premiums 
to  take  care  of  the  number  of  bank  failures;  it  inspects  insured  banks  to 
make  sure  they  are  not  going  to  fail.  It  is  possible,  of  course,  to  study  these 
administrative  processes  solely  as  degenerate  offshoots  of  the  judicial  system. 
It  would  seem  more  realistic,  however,  to  observe  that  each  such  activity  is, 
in  a  broad  sense,  a  part  of  the  management  of  the  real  estate  business,  the 
air  transport  business,  or  the  banking  business. 

Regulation  as  Partnership  in  Management.  Likewise,  the  Securities  and 
Exchange  Commission,  which  has  to  approve  registration  statements  before 
securities  are  offered  on  the  market,  must  act  more  like  a  partner  in  the 
management  of  the  issuing  enterprise  than  like  a  court  refereeing  disputes. 
An  investment  firm  must  put  its  securities  on  the  market  promptly  in  order 
to  make  a  profit,  and  any  public  question  about  their  soundness  would 
wreck  the  sale.  For  this  reason  it  is  no  wonder  that  the  securities  market 
in  general  prefers  to  have  questions  about  registration  statements  handled 
informally  and  privately  by  staff  members  of  the  commission,  rather  than 
aired  end  delayed  in  an  open  formal  hearing. 

Again,  as  with  all  administrative  activity,  the  primary  purpose  of  regu- 
lation is  to  protect  the  public  interest.  In  order  to  do  so,  an  administrative 
agency  may  make  use  of  specialists  who  are  also  valuable  to  the  regulated 
industry.  The  Department  of  Agriculture  grades  and  inspects  grain,  and 
inspects  perishable  commodities  and  imported  farm  products.  The  work  of 
its  inspectors,  scientists,  and  technicians— and  its  associated  state  and  local 
institutions— makes  up  the  national  research  program  for  agriculture.  The 
merchant-marine  inspectors  of  the  United  States  Coast  Guard  inspect  the 
construction,  maintenance,  and  repair  of  vessels.  An  inspector  in  a  ship- 
yard who  makes  sure  that  work  is  up  to  specifications  may  save  the  ship- 
builder and  the  ship  buyer  the  cost  of  hiring  men  for  some  of  the  same 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  525 

work.  And  a  marine  inspector  who  crawls  through  the  dirty  boiler  of  a 
cargo  vessel  in  order  to  tell  the  ship's  engineers  what  repairs  need  to  be 
made  for  the  next  voyage  may  be  engaging  in  quasi-judicial  activity,  but 
the  ship's  officers  look  on  him  as  an  expert  consultant,  and  if  they  think  of 
any  one  as  "regulating"  them  they  are  likely  to  think  of  their  company 
management. 

In  another  way  the  processes  of  administrative  regulation  are  more 
similar  to  those  of  management  than  to  judicial  proceedings.  The  adminis- 
trative agency  makes  a  continuous  positive  effort  to  prevent  adjudicatory 
cases  from  occurring  by  using  its  field  staff  to  educate  the  affected  interests. 
It  may  take  a  positive  lead  in  developing  new  techniques  and  new  methods 
of  management  for  the  regulated  interests.  The  United  States  Public  Health 
Service,  for  example,  is  not  merely  concerned  with  the  prosecution  of 
offenders,  but  also  with  the  development  of  new  methods  of  sanitation. 
The  Federal  Home  Loan  Bank  Board  does  not  merely  regulate  local  mort- 
gage-credit institutions;  it  develops  new  credit  opportunities  for  them,  and 
instructs  them  in  the  organization  of  their  business  and  the  techniques  of 
encouraging  savings  and  home  financing.  Because  such  agencies  specialize 
in  a  single  field  of  activity,  and  have  direct  administrative  control  over  their 
personnel,  they  can  develop  standard  national  policies  for  the  regulated 
interests  and  help  them  improve  their  operations. 

Some  of  the  agencies  in  question  have  a  still  more  positive  function  of 
over-all  management.  The  United  States  Maritime  Commission,  for  in- 
stance, has  relatively  few  regulatory  activities,  and  is  charged  with  the  job 
of  subsidizing  and  developing  the  American  merchant  marine.  The  Civil 
Aeronautics  Administration  decides  which  airlines  can  operate  where,  and 
sees  that  they  have  proper  airport  facilities,  flight  services,  qualified  crews, 
and  safe  equipment.  The  Federal  Reserve  System,  similarly,  has  some 
functions  of  adjudication;  yet  its  main  function  is  the  general  direction  of 
a  crucial  field  of  economic  activity. 

To  be  sure,  some  of  the  agencies  which  make  rules  and  hear  cases  do 
not  deal  with  a  single  type  of  business,  but  with  a  particular  aspect  of  many 
types  of  business.  The  several  regulatory  agencies  in  the  field  of  labor  rela- 
tions are  examples.  Other  examples  are  revenue-collection  agencies:  the 
Bureau  of  Internal  Revenue  and  the  Bureau  of  Customs.  The  Bureau  of 
Immigration  and  Naturalization  is  the  federal  administrative  agency  whose 
proceedings  most  closely  resemble  those  of  criminal  courts. 

Informal  Settlement  Versus  Formal  Adjudication.  Since  most  of  the 
agencies  with  rule-making  and  adjudicatory  functions  are  either  service 
agencies  in  the  main,  or  have  responsibilities  for  promoting  or  even  man- 
aging broad  fields  of  economic  interest,  they  should  not  be  considered  pri- 
marily as  tribunals  for  handling  complaints,  prosecuting  offenses,  or  settling 
disputes.  Such  business  is  generally  only  a  by-product  of  their  work,  or 


526  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

rather  it  is  only  the  way  of  disposing  of  their  unsatisfactory  commodities. 
For  their  basic  product  or  objective  is  the  cooperative  management  of  a 
national  activity,  and  any  case  in  which  the  private  parties  concerned  cannot 
be  led  to  cooperate  is  a  failure,  not  an  accomplishment. 

The  figures  cited  by  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administra- 
tive Procedure  illustrate  this  point.3  The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission 
arranged  voluntary  settlements  in  all  but  five  of  3,500  demurrage  complaints. 
The  Department  of  Agriculture,  administering  twenty-odd  regulatory  stat- 
utes, had  fewer  formal  hearings  than  one  per  day,  and  an  exception  was 
taken  to  an  examiner's  report  less  often  than  once  a  week.  The  National 
Labor  Relations  Board,  in  the  first  four  years  of  its  stormy  career,  had  to 
issue  formal  complaints  in  only  8  per  cent,  and  to  make  formal  decisions 
in  only  4  per  cent,  of  its  12,227  unfair  labor-practice  cases.  To  look  on 
regulatory  agencies  primarily  as  courts  and  to  make  them  follow  the  same 
procedure  would  be  to  organize  them  not  for  their  main  purpose,  but  for 
the  small  proportion  of  cases  in  which  their  purpose  could  not  be  accom- 
plished— as  if  business  were  to  be  organized  mainly  for  the  convenience  of 
referees  in  bankruptcy,  or  hospitals  for  the  convenience  of  undertakers. 

Balance  of  Public  Interests.  In  each  field  of  activity  a  balance  must  be 
struck  between  the  need  for  a  formalized  procedure — somewhat  resembling 
that  of  the  judicial  system — in  order  to  protect  people  from  arbitrary  action, 
and  the  need  for  administrative  initiative,  discretion,  and  dispatch,  in  order 
to  further  the  interests  of  the  people  concerned  and  to  protect  them  from 
frustrating  formalities.  The  balance  may  vary  from  time  to  time.  Since  the 
Interstate  Commerce  Commission  was  too  much  like  a  tribunal  to  manage 
the  national  transportation  system  in  wartime,  the  Office  of  Defense  Trans- 
portation was  created.  Since  the  United  States  Maritime  Commission  could 
not  operate  our  wartime  ocean  shipping  in  its  existing  form,  it  was  trans- 
formed for  that  purpose  into  the  War  Shipping  Administration,  while 
retaining  its  old  identity  for  other  operations. 

Those  who  mainly  wish  to  protect  private  interests  against  interference 
will  naturally — at  least  in  the  short  run — want  to  tip  the  balance  in  favor 
of  more  formalized  procedures.  Those  who  mainly  wish  to  accomplish 
broad  social  objectives  and  to  integrate  national  policy  will  generally  want 
to  tip  it  in  favor  of  more  administrative  discretion.  The  same  issue  may 
be  debated,  too,  in  another  aspect:  whether  a  regulatory  function,  especially 
in  the  federal  government,  should  be  lodged  in  an  ordinary  executive  depart- 
ment—as are  those  in  the  field  of  agriculture — or  in  an  independent  com- 
mission— as  are  most  of  those  that  deal  with  business.  However,  our  dif- 
ferences of  opinion  are  less  likely  to  be  irreconcilable  if  we  remember  that 
the  issuing  of  rules  and  the  hearing  of  cases  may  be  an  essential  part  of 

8  Op.  ck.  above  in  note  1,  p.  35.    Cf.  also  above  Ch.  10,  "Independent  Regulatory  Estab- 
lishments," sec.  2,  "The  Nature  and  Conduct  of  Regulatory  Business." 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  527 

an  administrative  function,  and  that  some  types  of  private  interests  may 
prefer  to  be  regulated  by  an  administrative  agency  that  is  also  concerned 
with  promoting  their  welfare,  rather  than  to  run  the  constant  risk  of  court 
action.  The  modern  maxim  is  to  temper  justice  with  subsidy. 

"Snuffing  the  Approach  of  Tyranny."  One  of  the  great  debates  of 
contemporary  public  affairs  is  that  of  the  traditional  lawyers  versus  the 
administrative  lawyers.  The  legal  profession  of  the  United  States  today — 
as  Edmund  Burke  remarked  of  it  in  1775 — is  "numerous  and  powerful" 
and  its  members  "augur  misgovernment  at  a  distance,  and  snuff  the  ap- 
proach of  tyranny  in  every  tainted  breeze."1  The  controversial  publications 
of  the  various  schools  of  legal  thought  illuminate  the  subject  of  administra- 
tive adjudication  and  "delegated  legislation"  for  the  student.  However, 
they  keep  the  spotlight  on  the  small  minority  of  cases  that  come  up  for 
formal  hearings — on  that  part  of  administration  that  follows,  or  may  per- 
haps be  made  to  follow,  procedures  similar  to  those  of  the  judiciary.  This 
preoccupation  with  the  margin  of  the  problem  is  typified  by  the  terms 
"administrative  process,"  "administrative  procedure,"  and  "administrative 
agency,"  which  in  most  lawyers'  studies  of  the  subject  are  used  to  refer  only 
to  the  agencies  that  issue  rules  and  adjudicate  private  rights,  and  their 
methods  of  doing  sol5 

A  leader  of  the  attack  on  administrative  adjudication  has  been  Professor 
Roscoe  Pound,  who  in  addition  to  his  authority  as  a  scholar  has  been  the 
spokesman  of  the  Committee  on  Administrative  Law  of  the  American  Bar 
Association.  To  avoid  the  impression  that  any  serious  writer  proposes  sim- 
ply to  abolish  administrative  adjudication,  we  should  stress  perhaps  that 
even  Pound  explains  the  necessity  for  its  development  and  its  existence.  He 
tells  how  the  United  States  was  "law  ridden"  in  the  nineteenth  century; 
how  the  demands  of  an  expanding  law  of  public  utilities  and  the  require- 
ments of  social  legislation  led  to  the  development  of  administrative  proce- 
dures and  regulatory  agencies;  how  the  judiciary  reviewed  the  decisions 
of  these  agencies  without  giving  any  weight  to  their  findings  of  fact,  thus 
forcing  them  to  follow  rules  of  evidence  suitable  only  for  jury  trials  in 
common-law  courts;  and,  in  consequence,  how  the  state  legislatures  and 
eventually  Congress  began  to  give  more  and  more  functions  to  administra- 
tive agencies  and  comparatively  fewer  to  the  courts.  He  mentions  work- 
men's compensation,  corporate  reorganization,  the  adjustment  of  private 
water  rights.  Then,  too,  for  the  past  sixty  years  "the  judiciary  has  been 
falling  into  line  and  .  .  .  powers  which  two  generations  ago  would  have 

4  "On  Conciliation  with  the  Colonies,"  Speeches  and  Letters  on  American  Affairs,  p.  95, 
New  York:  Dutton  (Everyman's  Library),  1931. 

5  This  type  of  definition  led  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Pro- 
cedure to  speculate  on  how  things  would  be  managed  "if  administrative  agencies  did  not  exist 
in  the  Federal  Government."    Op  cit.  above  in  note  1,  p.  13.    C/.  also  above  Ch.  17,  "Govern- 
ment by  Procedure." 


528  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

been  held  purely  judicial  and  jealously  guarded  from  executive  exercise  .  .  . 
are  now  cheerfully  conceded  to  boards  and  commissions."6 

On  the  other  hand,  Pound  charges  that  the  philosophies  of  Marx,  Freud, 
and  Einstein  have  led  certain  people  "to  believe  in  supermen  administrators 
free  from  the  checks  of  law  or  rights  or  judicial  review."7  This  belief, 
he  holds,  has  been  responsible  for  basically  unfair  procedures  in  administra- 
tive hearings.  The  courts,  he  says,  are  headed  by  judges  who  are  trained  to 
conform  to  known  standards  and  settled  ideals;  their  decisions  are  exposed 
to  the  criticism  of  an  informed  profession;  reports  of  the  cases  appear  in  the 
public  records;  and  individual  judgments  are  subject  to  review  by  a  bench 
whose  attitude  is  analytical.  The  administrative  agencies,  he  argues,  are 
under  none  of  these  safeguards.  Moreover,  they  have  an  "obstinate  tendency 
to  decide  without  a  hearing  or  without  hearing  one  of  the  parties";  they 
make  determinations  on  the  basis  of  private  consultations;  they  fail  to  dis- 
close to  affected  parties  the  evidence  on  which  their  orders  are  based;  and 
heads  of  administrative  agencies  act  on  abstracts  of  testimony  prepared  by 
irresponsible  subordinates,  without  studying  the  original  testimony.8  These 
evils  are  all  connected  with  the  fact  that  the  same  agency  is  acting  as  prose- 
cutor and  judge  in  the  same  case. 

Pound's  general  point  of  view  is  identical  with  the  basis  for  the  legisla- 
tion repeatedly  proposed  to  require  all  administrative  agencies  generally  to 
follow  a  single  pattern  of  procedure  in  their  rule-making  and  adjudication. 
In  Congress,  many  bills  of  this  type  have  been  introduced  in  recent  years. 
The  most  noted  was  the  Walter-Logan  bill  (H.  R.  6324,  76th  Congress, 
3d  Session),  which  was  passed  by  Congress  but  vetoed  by  the  President. 
This  bill  prescribed  a  single  rigid  method  for  the  issuing  of  regulations,  no 
matter  on  what  subject;  it  provided  for  very  extensive  judicial  review  of 
rules,  even  if  they  were  not  the  subject  of  controversy;  it  required  that  all 
adjudicatory  decisions  be  reviewed  by  superior  administrative  authorities, 
whether  any  one  appealed  or  not;  and,  while  excepting  decisions  of  certain 
agencies  entirely,  it  called  for  much  more  extensive  judicial  review  than  the 
courts  now  are  willing  or  are  permitted  by  statute  to  exercise.  At  the  same 
time  that  such  federal  legislation  was  being  widely  discussed,  the  state  of 
New  York  considered  a  constitutional  amendment  to  increase  the  frequency 
and  scope  of  judicial  review  of  administrative  actions. 

The  support  of  the  organized  legal  profession  for  such  measures  made 
a  thorough  study  of  them  essential.  The  President  accordingly  asked  the 
Attorney  General  in  1939  to  appoint  a  committee  to  study  the  possibility  of 
"procedural  reform  in  the  field  of  Administrative  law."  At  about  the  same 

6  Administrative  Law:  Its  Growth,  Procedure,  and  Significance,  p.  31,  Pittsburgh:  Uni- 
versity of  Pittsburgh  Press,  1942.  This  brief  study  ably  summarizes  Dean  Pound's  views  on 
the  subject. 

Tlbid.,  p.  22. 

8/£iW.,pp.60-75. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  529 

time  the  governor  of  New  York  appointed  Robert  M.  Benjamin  to  conduct 
a  similar  study  in  that  state. 

This  turn  of  events  was  similar  to  that  nearly  a  decade  earlier  in  Great 
Britain,  where  The  New  Despotism  by  Lord  Hewart,9  a  justice  of  the 
King's  Bench,  impelled  the  government  to  appoint  a  Committee  on  Minis- 
ters' Powers.  The  reports  of  this  committee,10  of  the  United  States  Attorney 
General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure,11  and  of  the  Benjamin 
inquiry12  in  the  state  of  New  York  give  a  remarkably  authoritative  and 
detailed  analysis  of  the  problem.  All  of  them  generally  agree  that  the  courts 
cannot  do  the  job  that  administrative  agencies  are  now  doing,  and  that 
administrative  agencies  could  not  do  it  themselves  if  any  one  made  them 
imitate  the  courts. 

In  addition  to  these  official  reports,  many  lawyers  have  undertaken  to 
refute  Pound  and  his  school  of  thought.  Several  of  them — notably  Judge 
Jerome  Frank  and  Dean  James  M.  Landis,  both  formerly  of  the  Securities 
and  Exchange  Commission,  and  Professor  Walter  Gellhorn,  director  of 
research  for  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  and  later  regional  counsel 
of  the  Office  of  Price  Administration — have  had  experience  in  federal  regu- 
latory agencies.  Frank's  lively  book,  //  Men  Were  Angels™  takes  issue 
pointedly  with  Pound  and  shows  in  great  detail  how  the  Securities  and 
Exchange  Commission  met  all  the  tests  of  fair  procedure  which  Pound 
argued  were  respected  only  in  the  courts.  Gellhorn's  Federal  Administrative 
Proceedings^  is  a  briefer  study  that  draws  on  the  work  of  the  Attorney 
General's  Committee  to  give  a  broad  picture  of  the  problem  of  administra- 
tive adjudication. 

Federal  Administrative  Procedure  Act.  One  might  have  assumed  that 
the  increasingly  realistic  and  mature  analysis  of  the  whole  problem  of  ad- 
ministrative law  would  have  encouraged  a  cautious  legislative  approach 
in  this  important  area,  and  one  intent  upon  preserving  the  desirable  flexi- 
bility of  administrative  practice.  Actually,  however,  those  forces  which 
originally  had  carried  forward  the  case  for  the  Walter-Logan  bill  resumed 
their  campaign  at  the  end  of  World  War  II  without  meeting  any  resistance 
in  Congress.  Although  the  findings  of  the  earlier  official  inquiries  com- 
pelled these  forces  to  compromise  on  many  details,  they  succeeded  in  press- 
ing for  considerably  more  extensive  judicial  review  of  administrative  actions; 

9  London:  Cosmopolitan,   1929;  rcpubhshcd  London:  Benn,  1945.    Cf.  also  above  Ch.  3, 
"Bureaucracy — Fact  and  Fiction,"  sec.  3,  "The  Charge  of  Despotism." 
AO  Cmd.  4060,  London,  1932. 

11  Op.  cit.  above  note  1. 

12  Benjamin,  Robert  M.,  Administrative  Adjudication  in  the  State  of  New  Yor^,  Albany, 
1942. 

13  New  York:  Harper,  1930. 

14  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1941.    Sec  also  Landis,  James  M.,  The  Administrative 
Process,  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press,  1938.     A  good  general  discussion  may  be  found 
in  Pcnnock,  Roland  J.,  Administration  and  the  Rule  of  Law,  New  York:  Farrar  &  Rinehart, 
1941. 


530  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

for  the  imposition  of  a  uniform  pattern  of  administrative  regulation  and 
adjudication;  and  for  more  highly  formalized  procedures  that  would  give 
private  interests  greater  opportunity  for  influencing  or  escaping  government 
regulation.  The  result  was  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of  1946. 

It  is  not  surprising  that  the  act  has  met  a  mixed  welcome.  The  Attorney 
General  has  greeted  it  as  "a  hopeful  prospect  of  achieving  reasonable  uni- 
formity and  fairness  in  administrative  procedures  without  at  the  same 
time  interfering  unduly  with  the  efficient  and  economical  operation  of  the 
Government."  Others,  and  especially  many  close  students  of  the  admin- 
istrative process,  have  recorded  grave  misgivings  about  the  anticipated 
impact  of  the  new  legislation  upon  regulatory  and  adjudicatory  methods. 

Much,  of  course,  will  depend  on  the  construction  of  the  act  by  the 
judiciary.  But  there  is  little  doubt  that  the  act  throws  a  heavy  burden  of 
court-like  formality  upon  government  regulation;  creates  novel  require- 
ments to  be  observed  by  administrative  agencies  at  the  threat  of  judicial 
invalidation  of  their  actions;  and,  by  extending  the  scope  of  judicial  review, 
invites  the  courts  to  become  virtual  partners  in  the  conduct  of  adminis- 
trative business. 

The  act  operates  on  the  basis  of  sweeping  definitions.  It  lumps  the 
rich  variety  of  administrative  actions  and  decisions  into  but  two  categories: 
rules  and  orders.  And  it  deals  with  both  categories  in  general  language, 
leaving  few  exceptions  from  the  requirements  it  lays  down  for  either 
category. 

Save  only  for  matters  of  legitimate  secrecy  on  the  one  hand  and  internal 
management  on  the  other,  the  act  stipulates  that  each  agency  must  publish 
in  the  Federal  Register  descriptions  of  its  structure,  including  its  field  or- 
ganization, to  indicate  the  allocation  of  authority;  statements  of  its  decision- 
making  methods,  together  with  precise  information  about  its  formal  and  in- 
formal procedures;  and  all  "substantive  rules"  as  well  as  pronouncements  of 
its  general  policy  and  interpretations  by  which  it  considers  itself  bound.  A 
similar  obligation  exists  with  respect  to  final  opinions  or  orders  in  the  ad- 
judication of  cases. 

Under  the  act,  rule-making  must  proceed  by  advance  notice  to  the  public 
and  by  opportunity  for  the  participation  of  private  interests  in  the  rule- 
making  process.  Formal  notice  and  participation  by  "all  interested  parties" 
is  also  required  in  administrative  adjudication.  Equally  rigid  is  the  statu- 
tory prescription  that  no  officer  engaged  in  the  fact-finding  aspect  of  the 
adjudicatory  process  may  take  part  in  the  decision  of  the  case.  Conversely, 
the  same  officer  having  presided  over  the  administrative  hearing  must  make 
the  initial  decision  or  the  recommendation  for  the  final  decision  of  the 
case.  An  initial  decision  is  subject  to  administrative  appeal,  compelling 
the  agency  to  go  once  more  over  the  entire  matter  in  the  same  manner  the 
initial  decision  was  reached.  All  agencies  must  secure  an  adequate  number 
of  hearing  examiners,  whose  separate  status  is  protected  by  special  guar- 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  531 

antees  and  who  are  not  to  be  drawn  into  any  other  phase  of  administrative 
business. 

The  act  is  emphatic  in  referring  to  the  courts  of  law  a  private  party 
"adversely  affected  or  aggrieved"  by  administrative  action.  As  to  the  scope 
of  judicial  review,  the  courts  are  directed  to  set  aside  any  administrative 
actions  deemed  void  for  various  reasons,  including  in  certain  types  of  cases 
actions  "unwarranted  by  the  facts."  On  the  side  of  questions  of  law,  the 
act  furnishes  a  fresh  incentive  for  the  courts  to  reach  out  into  the  area  of 
administrative  discretion.  However  these  statutory  clauses  may  eventually 
be  circumscribed  by  court  precedent,  it  appears  obvious  that  the  new  law 
is  likelier  to  increase  the  quantity  of  litigation  than  to  raise  the  standards 
of  administrative  justice. 

In  a  striking  manner,  once  again  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  turns 
the  spotlight  on  the  question  of  the  proper  general  approach  to  the  problem 
of  administrative  rule-making  and  adjudication.  Are  the  demands  of  justice 
and  those  of  administrative  efficiency  irreconcilable?  Must  we  concede  the 
need  for  reducing  the  promptness  and  resourcefulness  of  public  service  for 
the  benefit  of  the.  ordinary  citizen  because  important  private  interests  in 
the  community  have  to  be  specifically  safeguarded  by  elaborate  procedures 
subject  to  judicial  approbation?  As  one  way  of  seeking  an  answer  to  these 
questions,  we  should  find  it  helpful  to  consider  administrative  adjudication 
in  its  full  context. 

The  three  main  problems  of  administrative  adjudication  that  are  out- 
lined by  the  various  recent  studies  are  these:  the  rules  of  evidence  and  other 
procedures  that  govern  the  conduct  of  hearings;  judicial  review  of  adminis- 
trative decisions;  and  the  organization  of  administrative  agencies  to  prevent 
the  combination  of  managerial  and  adjudicative  functions  from  causing 
bias  in  the  trial  examiners  or  hearing  officers. 

3.  ADMINISTRATIVE  FAIRNESS  AND  JUDICIAL  REVIEW 

Rules  of  Evidence.  An  individual  whose  interests  are  impaired  by  ad- 
ministrative action  can  present  his  case  effectively  only  if  he  knows  the 
evidence  that  is  being  presented  against  him  and  has  a  fair  chance  to  refute 
it.  Some  of  the  most  serious  charges  against  administrative  procedure  have 
been  to  the  effect  that  these  essentials  of  fair  play  were  not  being  followed. 

The  Attorney  General's  Committee,  after  directing  its  expert  staff  to 
study  in  detail  the  procedures  of  nearly  all  federal  agencies  that  adjudicate 
private  rights,  found  "few  instances  of  indifference  on  the  part  of  the 
agencies  to  the  basic  values  which  underlie  a  fair  hearing,"  but  instead 
"a  healthy  self-criticism  and  considerable  alertness  to  fulfill  not  only  the 
letter  of  the  judicial  pronouncements  but  the  basic  implications  of  fairness 
in  hearing."15 

15  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  1,  p.  62. 


532  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

The  committee's  principal  criticism,  on  the  other  hand,  was  that  the 
administrative  hearings  were  not  administrative  enough.  In  its  own  lan- 
guage, it  blamed  "lengthy  hearings  and  incredibly  voluminous  records" 
for  burdensome  delays,  and  made  several  recommendations  for  shortening 
the  process.  One  of  them  was  that  administrative  agencies  borrow  an  in- 
formal and  expeditious  procedure  from  the  courts— the  "pretrial  hearing," 
which  is  a  hearing  conducted  in  the  manner  of  a  conference  between  a 
judge  and  the  lawyers  in  the  case,  using  more  direct  methods  of  getting  at 
the  facts  than  formal  examination  and  cross-examination. 

Perhaps  to  the  amazement  of  those  who  suspected  that  political  trends 
under  the  New  Deal  had  led  to  unfair  administrative  practices,  the  Attorney 
General's  Committee  directed  some  of  its  more  severe  censure  on  points  of 
procedure,  not  against  any  of  the  new  regulatory  agencies,  but  against  two 
of  the  older  departments.  It  criticized  the  War  Department  for  failing  to 
inform  interested  parties— other  than  the  applicants  themselves-— of  the 
reasons  justifying  a  license  for  the  erection  of  structures  in  navigable  water- 
ways. And  it  rebuked  the  Post  Office  Department  for  neglecting  to  notify 
publishers  of  their  statutory  right  to  a  hearing  before  revoking  second-class 
mailing  privileges,  even  though  they  had  always  been  given  an  opportunity 
to  state  their  case  in  writing. 

Neither  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  nor  the  Benjamin  report  to 
the  governor  of  New  York  recommended  one  single  code  of  administrative 
procedure.  Only  a  minority  of  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  did.  The 
majority  held  that  the  advantages  of  diversity  to  accommodate  particular 
types  of  regulatory  authority  were  considerable,  and  therefore  made  nu- 
merous minor  recommendations  on  the  procedure  of  individual  agencies  as 
a  result  of  the  committee's  research.16 

Spot  Chec\  of  Judicial  Review.  The  problem  of  judicial  review  has  been 
magnified  out  of  all  importance,  for  in  numerous  types  of  cases  that  are 
handled  by  administrative  agencies  the  citizen  would  get  little  or  no  tangible 
protection  from  appealing  to  the  courts.  Many  administrative  agencies,  in 
matters  of  adjudication,  deal  with  questions  that  have  to  be  answered  imme- 
diately in  order  to  prevent  hardship,  or  that  individually  do  not  justify  the 
cost  of  legal  proceedings.  Thus  an  unsuccessful  claimant  for  a  small  social 
security  benefit  will  usually  not  hire  a  lawyer  to  contest  a  doubtful  case, 
simply  because  the  odds  are  not  worth  the  cost.  A  grower  will  not  t?ke 
to  court  a  decision  by  an  examiner  of  the  United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture  condemning  a  carload  of  perishable  commodities,  for  his  goods 
will  decay  before  they  could  be  introduced  as  evidence.  A  securities  broker 
will  find  little  satisfaction  in  appealing  from  an  adverse  decision  of  the 

16  Sec  the  scries  of  monographs  on  individual  agencies  issued  by  the  Attorney  General's 
Committee.  Study  of  almost  any  two  of  the  monographs  will  suffice  to  show  the  reader  how 
considerably  the  subject  matter  and  the  procedure  of  the  various  agencies  differ  from  one 
another. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  533 

Securities  and  Exchange  Commission  on  the  listing  of  a  security,  for  the 
opportunity  to  sell  it  profitably  may  have  gone. 

To  depend  mainly  on  judicial  review  in  these  cases  would  be  futile. 
The  chief  problem  is  how  to  organize  on  a  fair  basis  the  system  of  rendering 
the  original  decision.  The  volume  of  administrative  decisions  alone  would 
make  it  unwise  to  rely  too  extensively  on  review  by  the  courts.  It  is  no 
more  reasonable  to  ask  the  courts  to  decide  anew  any  considerable  portion 
of  administrative  decisions  than  to  ask  the  Supreme  Court  to  consider  again 
most  of  the  cases  decided  by  lower  courts. 

What  the  courts  can  do,  however,  is  to  protect  the  fundamental  rights 
of  citizens  to  fair  treatment  in  the  hearing  of  their  cases,  and  to  maintain 
the  basic  political  and  constitutional  relationship  between  the  administrative 
agency  and  other  branches  of  government.  If  the  courts  are  to  do  this 
effectively,  they  must  restrict  themselves  to  two  questions:  first,  the  type  of 
case  which  they  will  review  at  all;  and  second,  the  extent  to  which  they  will 
give  weight  to  the  original  decision  of  the  administrative  agency. 

In  four  general  ways  the  federal  courts  have  narrowed  down  the  number 
of  cases  they  will  review,  even  though  they  have  avoided  a  statement  of 
principles  and  have  carefully  maintained  their  discretion  to  consider  each 
case  as  it  comes  up.  One  such  restriction  is  that  the  individual  appealing 
from  the  administrative  decision  must  have  "legal  standing" — that  is,  in 
general,  he  must  be  "adversely  affected"  by  the  decision.  Another  is  that 
the  administrative  decision  must  be  a  final  one.  No  one  may  come  to  the 
court  with  a  case  until  he  has  done  all  he  can  to  get  a  favorable  decision 
from  the  administrative  agency.  Third,  there  is  some  question  of  whether 
courts  will  generally  review  an  administrator's  refusal  to  take  action — such 
as  refusal  to  issue  a  license — even  though  the  Supreme  Court  in  1938  with- 
drew its  earlier  doctrine  that  "negative  orders"  were  not  reviewable.  Fourth, 
courts  will  not  review— sometimes  by  self-denial,  sometimes  because  of 
statutory  limitations — some  types  of  decisions  that  seem  particularly  suited 
to  administrative  discretion.  Examples  are  a  decision  that  a  contractor  on  a 
government  project  must  pay  certain  wage  rates,  or  decisions  of  the  Veter- 
ans Administration  with  respect  to  certain  classes  of  benefits  to  veterans.17 

Scope  of  Judicial  Review.  Much  more  important,  however,  than  the 
question  of  whether  or  not  to  review  a  case  is  the  question  of  how  far  a 
court  is  to  go  in  its  review.  For  just  as  the  administrative  agency  has  no 
more  extensive  rule-making  or  quasi-legislative  power  than  the  legislature 
intended  to  give  it,  so  it  has  only  as  much  power  to  make  decisions  as  the 
courts  leave  in  its  hands.  An  illustration  of  the  way  in  which  the  judiciary 
may  take  over  decisions  that  are  the  very  heart  of  administration  may  be 
chosen  from  the  annals  of  New  York  state  government.  In  1903,  the  Court 
of  Appeals  held  that  the  duty  of  classification  of  positions — as  competitive, 

!7  Cf.  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure,  ofi.  cit.  above  in  note  1, 
pp.  84-86. 


534  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

noncompctitivc,  or  exempt—- under  the  civil  service  law  was  quasi-judicial 
in  its  nature,  and  could  be  reviewed  by  the  courts  by  writ  of  certiorari, 
much  like  any  decision  of  a  lower  court.  After  a  few  years  the  Court  of 
Appeals  came  to  the  uncomfortable  conclusion  that  it  had — in  its  own  words 
—"in  effect  assumed  the  functions  of  the  Civil  Service  Commissioners,  for 
every  challenged  decision  of  these  officers  was  brought  to  this  court  as  a 
question  of  law."18  Accordingly,  it  reversed  itself;  decided  that  the  function 
was  not  judicial  or  even  quasi-judicial;  held  that  such  decisions  could  be 
reviewed  only  by  writ  of  mandamus;  and  explained  that,  while  clear  failure 
or  refusal  of  the  Civil  Service  Commission  to  do  its  duty  could  be  reviewed, 
the  court  would  not  reverse  any  decision,  even  though  it  might  differ  with 
its  wisdom,  if  there  was  "a  fair  and  reasonable  ground  for  difference  of 
opinion." 

In  short,  since  every  act  of  a  public  official  must  be  based  on  legal  authori- 
zation, courts  may  stretch  their  logic  a  bit  and  make  nearly  any  type  of 
administrative  decision  all  over  again.  The  stretching  would  not  be  too 
difficult.  It  is  a  settled  principle  that  the  courts  have  the  power  to  review 
questions  of  law,  since  otherwise  the  citizen  would  have  no  way  to  appeal 
against  the  actions  of  an  official  who  plainly  acted  illegally.  It  is  a  com- 
monplace among  lawyers,  however,  that  no  clear  distinction  exists  between 
questions  of  law  and  questions  of  fact,  since  their  subject  matter  is  basically 
the  same.  As  one  frequently  quoted  passage  runs,  "the  knife  of  policy 
alone  effects  an  artificial  cleavage"  between  the  two  questions,  and  fur- 
thermore, "at  the  point  where  the  court  chooses  to  draw  the  line  between 
public  interest  and  private  right."19 

To  illustrate  this  point,  we  may  take  the  classic  case  of  Miller  v.  Horton.20 
A  public  health  official  killed  a  horse  that  in  his  judgment  had  the  glanders. 
The  jury  decided  that  the  horse  had  not  really  had  the  glanders  after  all; 
that  the  official  who  thought  it  had  was  wrong;  and  that  therefore  he  had 
not  had  legal  authority  to  kill  the  horse  and  must  pay  for  it.  The  law  usually 
authorizes  an  official  to  act  only  in  certain  circumstances  and  for  certain 
purposes.  If  a  judge  wants  to  reverse  the  official's  decision  on  the  facts  of 
the  situation,  he  can  often  find  the  facts  so  thoroughly  mixed  up  with  the 
legal  issues  involved  that  a  review  ostensibly  of  the  law  will  take  care  of 
the  facts  as  well. 

Legitimate  Judicial  Concerns.  If  the  courts  were  generally  preoccupied 
with  private  rights  and  careless  of  the  public  interest,  logic  alone  would  not 
stop  them  from  reducing  the  original  administrative  ruling  to  little  more 

18  Simons  v.  McGuire,  204  N.  Y.  253,  257-258,  97  N.  E.  526,  527  (1912),  as  quoted 
by  Hart,  James,  "Judicial  Review  of  Administrative  Action:  A  Thesis,"  George  Washington 
Law  Review,  1941,  Vol.  9,  p.  501. 

19  Dickinson,  John,  Administrative  Justice  and  the  Supremacy  of  Law,  p.  55,  Cambridge: 
Harvard  University  Press,  1927. 

20  152  Mass.  540,  26  N.  E.  100,  10  L.  R.  A.  116,  23  Am.  St.  Rep.  850  (1891). 


THE   JUDICIAL  TEST  535 

than  a  formal  preliminary  to  the  judicial  decision.  Fortunately,  the  courts 
in  the  main  do  no  such  thing.  Their  prevailing  philosophy  has  followed 
the  election  returns  in  accepting  the  idea  that  considerations  of  public  in- 
terest have  greatly  expanded  as  our  economic  system  has  increased  its 
interdependences.  Accordingly,  when  a  court  reviews  an  administrative  ad- 
judication, more  often  than  not  it  adjusts  the  scope  of  its  review  to  the 
extent  to  which  fundamental  principles  appear  to  be  involved,  much  as  an 
executive  gives  his  attention  to  the  more  significant  problems  of  administra- 
tion and  leaves  others  to  his  subordinates. 

Above  all,  a  higher  court  will  thoroughly  review  cases  involving  con- 
stitutional rights.  It  may  consider  all  the  aspects  of  such  a  case  anew,  giv- 
ing comparatively  little  weight  even  in  questions  of  fact  to  the  original 
decision  of  an  administrative  agency.  The  next  most  intensive  review  will 
be  given  those  cases  in  which  the  problem  arises  of  whether  an  agency 
acted  outside  its  statutory  authority.  Even  though  such  questions  of  law 
are  entangled  with  questions  of  fact,  the  courts  will  certainly  not  hesitate 
to  reverse  an  agency's  decision  when  that  decision  was  clearly  beyond  its 
legal  power. 

A  part  of  the  question  of  whether  the  agency  acted  legally  or  not  is 
this:  Did  it  follow  a  fair  procedure?  The  courts  are  likely  to  insist  rigor- 
ously on  the  fundamentals  of  fair  play — the  right  to  face  and  cross-examine 
witnesses  for  the  other  side,  and  so  on.  On  the  other  hand,  the  courts  are 
not  likely  to  insist  that  specialized  administrative  agencies  with  expert  trial 
examiners  be  bound  by  the  elaborate  rules  of  evidence  that  were  developed 
to  help  a  judge  keep  a  jury  of  laymen  from  being  bamboozled. 

American  courts,  it  should  be  added,  are  still  somewhat  more  inclined 
than  English  courts  to  assume  that  an  administrative  agency  has  acted 
fairly  only  if  it  has  acted  like  a  court.  The  Arlidge  case21  in  Great  Britain 
established  the  principle  that  administrative  agencies  might  conform  to 
"methods  of  natural  justice"  without  following  "lawyer-like  methods."  In 
contrast  to  this,  in  the  equally  famous  Morgan  cases22  in  the  United  States, 
the  Supreme  Court,  in  regard  to  certain  procedures,  considered  the  function 
of  the  Secretary  of  Agriculture  "a  duty  akin  to  that  of  a  judge." 

Legislative  and  Judicial  Standards  of  Review.  The  courts  will  rely  most 
on  the  administrative  agency's  decision,  and  insist  least  on  their  own  point 
of  view,  in  questions  that  are  clearly  and  solely  questions  of  fact.  In  re- 
viewing such  questions,  the  courts  have  come  more  and  more  to  the  point  of 
trying  to  decide  not  whether  the  administrative  agency  made  the  correct 
decision — which  could  only  mean  the  same  decision  the  court  would  have 
made  if  it  had  been  the  agency—but  whether  the  decision  was  made  rea- 

21  Local  Government  Board  v.  Arlidge,  L.  R.  (1915),  Appeal  Cases,  120. 
22 Morgan  v.  United  States,  298  U.  S.  468  (1936);  304  U.  S.  1  (1938):  304  U.  S.  23 
(1938). 


536  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

sonably  and  on  the  basis  of  substantial  evidence.  Language  to  bring  about 
this  effect  has  been  incorporated  in  legislation  defining  the  extent  of  court  re- 
view of  the  decisions  of  certain  federal  agencies:  "findings  of  fact  by  the 
Commission,  if  supported  by  substantial  evidence,  shall  be  conclusive  unless 
it  shall  clearly  appear  that  the  findings  of  the  Commission  are  arbitrary  and 

•      •  »*OQ 

capricious.  /d 

There  has  been  a  measure  of  legislative  maneuvering  over  the  exact  lan- 
guage of  this  formula.  But  as  long  as  the  general  idea  is  put  across  that 
the  courts  are  not  to  substitute  their  judgment  for  that  of  administrative 
agencies  in  cases  the  latter  have  decided,  the  exact  words  of  the  formula  do 
not  matter  much.  Congress  declared  the  findings  of  the  National  Labor 
Relations  Board  conclusive  if  "supported  by  evidence,"  without  using  the 
term  "substantial"  or  anything  like  it,  but  the  Supreme  Court  held  that 
if  the  evidence  was  not  substantial  it  was  not  evidence,  and  the  omission 
of  the  word  made  no  difference."4 

Those  who  wish  to  broaden  the  scope  of  judicial  review  have  argued 
that  administrative  decisions  ought  to  be  supported  by  the  "weight  of  the 
evidence."  However,  the  question  cannot  be  solved  by  any  such  juggling 
of  words.  It  is  simply  the  issue  of  whether  or  not  the  courts  are  going  to 
let  the  administrative  agencies  do  their  jobs.  And  in  recent  years  the  judi- 
cial point  of  view  generally  has  been  a  more  sympathetic  one.25 

In  general,  court  review  of  administrative  decisions  and  orders  is  least 
useful  on  those  aspects  of  a  case  that  require  discretion — the  selection  of  one 
choice  among  several  with  nearly  equal  advantages — or  call  for  technical  or 
scientific  qualifications.  It  is  most  useful,  on  the  other  hand,  on  those  as- 
pects of  a  case  that  involve  the  protection  of  definite  individual  rights  or 
personal  liberties  against  arbitrary,  unreasonable,  or  careless  official  action. 
However,  no  line  can  be  drawn  in  advance  between  the  various  aspects  of 
any  single  case.  Just  as  the  judge  may  substitute  his  personal  predilections 
for  the  scientific  opinion  of  the  expert,  so  the  expert  may  come  to  believe 
that  his  science  justifies  exceeding  his  authority.  In  the  long  run,  mutual 
respect  by  judges  and  administrators  will  help  maintain  a  sense  of  jurisdic- 
tional  differentiation  between  them,  particularly  if  an  aggressive  and  well- 
informed  public  opinion  watches  the  entire  process  of  adjudication. 

23  Communications  Act  of  1934  (48  Stat.  1094,  47  U.  S.  C.  402e). 

^Consolidated  Edison  Co.  v.  NX.R.B.,  305  U.  S.  197,  229  (1938). 

25  The  Emergency  Price  Control  Act  of  1942  provided  that  appeals  against  regulations  of 
the  Office  of  Price  Administration  had  to  be  made  first  to  the  price  administrator,  and  that 
any  one  denied  relief  might  then  ask  a  special  emergency  court  of  appeals  to  issue  an  injunc- 
tion against  a  regulation,  but  only  if  the  regulation  was  found  to  be  "not  in  accordance  with 
law,  or  ...  arbitrary  or  capricious."  In  Yakus  v.  United  States,  321  U.  S.  414  (1943),  the 
Supreme  Court  upheld  not  only  the  authority  of  Congress  to  delegate  "legislative"  power — 
"Congress  is  not  confined  to  that  method  of  executing  its  policy  which  involves  the  least  pos- 
sible delegation  of  discretion  to  administrative  officers" — but  also  the  unusual  provisions  for 
review  of  the  validity  of  regulations  only  in  accordance  with  a  single  procedurr 


THE   JUDICIAL  TEST  537 

4.  THE  ORGANIZATION  OF  ADJUDICATION 

Prosecutor-and-]udge  Agencies.  Since  practical  limitations  apply  to  the 
usefulness  of  judicial  review  in  a  dynamic  administrative  system,  it  is  all 
the  more  important  to  organize  properly  the  hearing  activities  of  the  gov- 
ernment agencies  concerned.  This  problem,  it  is  true,  has  nothing  to  do 
with  the  great  mass  of  business  of  most  of  the  agencies,  which  is  handled 
by  informal  settlement.  Nor  has  it  anything  to  do  with  the  business  of 
some  of  the  agencies,  which  proceeds  by  such  techniques  as  scientific  inspec- 
tion and  makes  little  or  no  use  of  formal  hearings.  However,  the  agency 
that  holds  formal  hearings  must  take  care  to  organize  itself  so  as  to  avoid 
the  charge — and  any  basis  for  the  suspicion — that  its  interest  in  initiating  the 
case  leads  it  to  be  unfair  in  the  hearing. 

This  is  the  question  of  whether  a  single  agency  should  be  both  prose- 
cutor and  judge  in  the  same  case.  The  question  is  partly  fallacious,  but 
nevertheless  it  has  made  many  people  doubt  the  fairness  of  administrative 
procedure.  The  element  of  fallacy  in  the  question  is  that  an  agency  is  not 
a  single  person.  The  agency  may  be  an  extremely  large  organization — 
much  larger  than  the  whole  government  of  the  United  States  a  century 
ago — and  it  is  surely  as  possible  to  set  up  within  it  a  system  of  checks  and 
balances  as  it  was  to  create  such  a  system  in  our  national  government. 

The  agency  may  well  be  expected  to  have  a  bias  in  favor  of  a  certain 
policy — the  policy  which  it  is  instructed  by  statute  to  enforce.  And  if  cer- 
tain groups  oppose  that  policy  it  is  possible  for  the  agency  to  develop  a  bias 
against  those  groups.  Even  judges,  however,  are  not  supposed  to  be  com- 
pletely neutral  toward  the  laws  they  are  enforcing,  or  toward  those  who  fail 
to  obey  the  laws.  They  are  only  supposed  to  reserve  judgment  on  the 
question  of  whether  any  given  individual  has  in  fact  disobeyed  the  laws. 
Still,  administrative  agencies  are  particularly  likely  to  be  directed  to  enforce 
laws  that  are  vigorously  opposed  by  one  or  another  respectable  economic 
interest,  and  their  unpopularity  may  sometimes  be  a  measure  of  their 
effectiveness. 

Administrative  agencies  may  be  reluctant  to  create  formal  hearing  units, 
and  to  set  off  the  personnel  that  hear  cases  from  those  who  investigate  and 
initiate  them.  Their  reluctance  may  come  from  fear  of  reducing  the  scope 
of  their  discretion;  fear  of  tying  their  hands  with  their  own  procedure;  or 
fear  of  inviting  additional  judicial  review  by  appearing  to  be  in  effect 
subordinate  courts.  Such  fear  does  not  seem  unreasonable  if  we  think  of 
the  point  of  view  of  the  traditional  lawyers,  who  are  still  likely  to  hold  with 
the  late  A.  V.  Dicey  that  administrative  law  does  not  exist  in  English- 
speaking  countries. 

Dicey,  in  his  classic  on  the  law  of  the  British  Constitution,26  emphasized 

36  Dicey,  A.  V.,  Introduction  to  the  Study  of  the  Law  of  the  Constitution,  8th  cd.,  New 
York:  Macmillan,  1915. 


538  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

the  facts  that  any  citizen  could  go — as  he  still  can  go — to  the  regular  court 
if  any  official  damaged  him  by  acting  beyond  his  legal  authority;  and  that 
under  the  Continental  system  of  administrative  law  the  citizen  is  not  always 
able  to  do  this.  What  he  failed  to  see  was  that  the  common-law  court  may 
be  too  slow  and  expensive  to  help  the  citizen  or  may  achieve  nothing  if  the 
official  act  which  damaged  him  was  performed  within  the  law,  while  an 
administrative  court  might  give  him  quick  and  cheap  relief.  On  points 
like  these,  Dicey's  Continental  critics  scored  heavily,  especially  those  who 
like  Duguit27  emphasized  the  service  functions  of  public  administration 
and  the  role  of  governmental  authority  in  giving  effect  to  democratic 
policies. 

Continental  Administrative  Courts.  English-speaking  countries  were 
reluctant  to  permit  executive  departments  to  hear  and  decide  cases  after  the 
manner  of  a  court.  They  showed  even  greater  reluctance  to  evolve  special- 
ized branches  of  the  judiciary  to  handle  the  new  types  of  cases  that  arose 
with  the  extension  of  government  functions.  These  attitudes  kept  the 
United  States  and  Great  Britain,  in  some  types  of  cases,  from  developing  as 
effective  machinery  for  protecting  private  rights  as  was  brought  into  being 
by  the  administrative  courts  of  Continental  Europe. 

The  French  established  a  system  of  administrative  courts  as  a  result  of 
the  decision,  effected  in  their  revolutionary  constitution,  to  separate  the 
powers  of  government  with  logical  thoroughness.  They  carried  their  logic 
so  far  as  to  forbid  the  judiciary  to  interfere  with  administrative  acts,  and 
initially  left  the  citizen  with  no  recourse  except  appeal  to  the  higher  level 
of  administration.  The  executive  branch  subsequently  organized  a  formal 
system  of  inferior  and  superior  councils  to  hear  such  appeals.  These  coun- 
cils secured  increasing  independence  as  administrative  courts,  hearing  all 
kinds  of  cases  arising  out  of  the  relationship  between  public  authorities  and 
the  citizens. 

The  Napoleonic  period  carried  French  administrative  influences  through- 
out most  of  Europe.  The  system  of  administrative  courts,  with  national 
variations,  eventually  became  Continental  in  its  scope.  At  the  highest  stage 
of  its  development,  it  had  several  fairly  general  characteristics.28  It  was 
a  system  of  judge-made  law,  in  that  the  administrative  judges  built  up  an 
expanding  body  of  precedents  in  the  process  of  interpreting  statutes  and 
deciding  cases.  There  was  a  hierarchy  of  courts,  with  appeal  from  the  lower 
to  the  higher.  The  procedure  made  it  relatively  easy  and  inexpensive  for 
the  average  citizen  to  get  a  decision. 

Since  among  the  lower  courts  there  was  a  considerable  measure  of  spe- 
cialization like  that  of  executive  departments,  the  judges  were  closely  in 

27  Duguit,  Leon.  Law  in  the  Modem  State,  New  York:  Viking,  1919. 

28  For  a  summary  description  and  citations  to  the  literature  on  this  subject,  see  Morstein 
Marx,  Fritz,  "Comparative  Administrative  Law:  The  Continental  Alternative,"  University  of 
Pennsylvania  Law  Review,  1942,  Vol.  91,  p.  118  ff. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  539 

touch  with  administrative  developments,  and  in  an  excellent  position  to 
interpret  the  motivation  and  to  control  the  discretion  of  officials.  At  the 
same  time,  the  judges,  being  drawn  from  the  ranks  of  the  administrative 
career  service,  were  sympathetic  toward  the  public  purposes  of  government 
agencies.  Career  administrators  themselves  were  trained  in  public  law  as 
well  as  for  management.  For  this  reason,  and  because  administrative  actions 
did  not  come  before  less  well-informed  ordinary  courts,  government  depart- 
ments were  not  in  need  of  large  legal  staffs  who  might — as  in  the  United 
States— have  carried  on  feuds  with  operating  officials. 

American  Alternatives.  The  possibility  of  bringing  forth  a  more  sys- 
tematic body  of  administrative  law  in  this  country  has  led  scholars  of  sound 
reputation  to  propose  a  special  court  of  appeals  for  administrative  cases.29 
This  is  no  startling  proposal  in  view  of  the  fact  that  Congress  has  set  up 
several  constitutional  curiosities  sometimes  called  legislative  courts,  such 
as  the  Tax  Court  and  the  Court  of  Claims,  which  hear  appeals  from  admin- 
istrative agencies.  And  there  is  reason  for  reflecting  on  the  merits  of  a 
structure  of  administrative  courts.  Fritz  Morstein  Marx,  whose  experience 
as  a  public  official  in  republican  Germany  reinforces  his  opinions  as  a  stu- 
dent of  administration,  has  argued  for  a  general  system  of  administrative 


courts.80 


On  the  other  hand,  several  proposals  have  been  advanced  for  improving 
the  institutions  of  administrative  law  and  adjudication  without  setting  up 
new  courts.  Any  proposal  for  instituting  administrative  courts  in  American 
government  raises  the  question  of  whether  they  would  be  in  the  executive 
or  the  judicial  branch  or,  like  the  Tax  Court,  in  a  sort  of  quasi-legislative 
limbo.  If  they  were  clearly  established  in  the  judicial  branch,  it  might  be  dif- 
ficult to  keep  their  personnel  and  procedures  from  taking  on  the  character- 
istics of  other  courts.  The  principal  official  committees  that  have  touched 
on  the  subject  in  recent  years  have  avoided  this  whole  question,  perhaps  pre- 
ferring to  leave  the  process  of  administrative  adjudication  in  the  executive 
branch,  or  in  the  independent  commissions  and  boards  in  whatever  branch 
they  may  be. 

The  Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Administrative  Procedure  pro- 
posed to  create  a  separate  corps  of  hearing  commissioners  and  to  establish 
a  staff  agency  to  keep  an  eye  on  regulatory  procedures.  The  committee 
suggested  the  formation  of  an  office  of  federal  administrative  procedure, 
headed  by  a  three-man  board — one  judge,  the  director  of  the  administrative 
office  of  the  United  States  courts,  and  a  director  of  federal  administrative 
procedure  to  be  appointed  by  the  President  for  a  seven-year  term.  This 
office  would  keep  in  touch  with  federal  procedures  of  adjudication  and  regu- 

20  Cf.  Blachly,  Frederick  F.  and  Oatman,  Miriam  E.,  "A  United  States  Court  of  Appeals  for 
Administration,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1942  Vol 
221,  p.  170  ff. 

80  Sec  loc.  cit.  above  note  28. 


540  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

lation  through  liaison  officers  designated  by  each  agency,  and  would  study 
and  recommend  improvements.  Each  agency  would  nominate  its  own 
hearing  commissioners  for  seven-year  appointments,  but  the  Office  of  Fed- 
eral Administrative  Procedure  would  have  to  approve  the  appointments, 
and  the  hearing  commissioners  could  be  removed  only  by  this  office. 

The  minority  of  the  Attorney  General's  Committee  wished  to  go  further 
than  the  majority  in  applying  a  judicial  pattern  to  the  organization  and  pro- 
cedure of  administrative  adjudication.  They  urged  the  enactment  of  a  code 
of  administrative  procedure.  It  would  separate  by  statutory  provision  the 
functions  of  prosecuting  and  judging,  define  the  scope  of  judicial  review, 
and  establish  uniform  standards  of  fair  administrative  procedure. 

The  Benjamin  report  on  Administrative  Adjudication  in  the  State  of 
New  York  recommended  a  similar  central  executive  agency,  a  division  of 
administrative  procedure.  Perhaps  it  is  significant  that  Benjamin,  although 
aided  by  a  competent  staff,  was  solely  responsible  for  his  report,  instead  of 
submitting  it  through  a  committee.  For  the  Benjamin  report  recommended 
that  the  division  of  administrative  procedure  be  headed  by  a  single  director 
instead  of  by  a  board.  The  director  was  to  serve  at  the  pleasure  of  the 
governor,  and  the  division  was  to  be  principally  advisory  in  its  function, 
having  nothing  to  do  with  the  appointment  of  trial  examiners.  The  Ben- 
jamin report  emphasized  that  administrative  adjudication  is  an  essential  part 
of  administration,  which  must  be  a  function  of  the  executive  branch.  The 
threat  to  detach  it  from  the  executive  branch  had  been  more  serious  in 
New  York  than  in  the  federal  government,  in  view  of  the  constitutional 
amendment  proposed  in  New  York  to  provide  judicial  review  of  the  facts 
as  well  as  of  the  law  of  virtually  all  decisions  of  administrative  officers  and 
agencies.81 

Executive  Integration  of  Regulatory  Bodies.  Even  more  care  to  see  that 
the  present  administrative  responsibility  for  adjudication  should  not  slip 
away  into  the  judicial  branch  was  shown  several  years  earlier  by  the 
President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management.  It  dealt  with 
the  administration  of  that  function  as  it  discussed  the  problem  of  the 
organization  of  the  independent  regulatory  boards  and  commissions.32  The 
President's  Committee  freely  admitted  that  the  same  personnel  should  not 
prepare  and  prosecute  cases  and  then  sit  in  judgment  on  them.  "This  not 
only  undermines  judicial  fairness;  it  weakens  public  confidence  in  that  fair- 
ness."33 The  committee  put  still  more  emphasis,  however,  on  the  necessity 

81  Sec  Parratt,  Spencer  D.,  "The  Benjamin  Report,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1942, 
Vol.  2,  p.  348  ff.,  as  well  ?s  the  Benjamin  report  itself:  op.  cit.  above  note  12. 

82  See  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Studies, 
Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937.    One  of  the  special  studies  was  "The  Problem 
of  the  Independent  Regulatory  Commissions,"  by  Robert  E.  Cushman,  from  which  the  pro- 
posal of  the  committee  on  the  subject  was  drawn.     See  also  Cushman's  more  recent  book, 
The  Independent  Regulatory  Commissions,  New  York:  Oxford  University  Press,  1941. 

88  Report  cit.  above  in  note  32,  p.  40. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  54l 

of  unifying  the  executive  branch  to  keep  the  federal  government  from  bog- 
ging down,  like  some  state  governments,  by  the  weight  and  confusion  of 
independent  and  irresponsible  units.  For,  in  a  supporting  staff  study,  Pro- 
fessor Robert  E.  Cushman  pointed  out  that  it  was  very  difficult  to  disen- 
tangle the  administrative  and  judicial  phases  of  regulatory  work — a  fact 
on  which  all  observers  of  the  subject  appear  to  agree — and  that  some  of  the 
regulatory  commissions  do  not  merely  regulate  in  the  sense  that  a  police 
department  or  a  public  health  officer  regulates.  For  example,  he  observed 
that  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  "regulates  and  manages  the  land 
transportation  system  of  the  nation."  It  is,  "in  short,  a  little  government  in 
itself  set  up  for  the  purpose  of  governing  the  railroads."  And,  although  its 
paths  cross  that  of  the  President,  it  has  no  formal  responsibility  to  him. 

The  President's  Committee  proposed,  as  Cushman  suggested,  a  formula 
to  provide  both  judicial  fairness  and  executive  integration.  It  recommended 
that  the  independent  commissions  and  boards  be  put  into  the  executive 
departments  as  bureaus  or  divisions,  and  that  each  of  them  be  divided  into 
two  sections.  One  would  be  an  administrative  section,  organized  and  staffed 
like  any  other  bureau,  which  would  handle  the  administrative,  rule-making, 
and  investigating  phases  of  the  work.  If  the  cases  to  be  handled  were  nu- 
merous and  routine,  it  would  also  conduct  the  hearings  in  the  first  instance. 
The  other  would  be  the  judicial  section,  including  members  appointed  by 
the  President  and  approved  by  the  Senate  for  long  and  staggered  terms. 
It  would  be  in  the  department  only  for  housekeeping  purposes.  It  would 
hear  cases  and  appeals. 

Some  of  these  judicial  sections  might  well  develop  into  administrative 
courts,  as  Cushman  pointed  out,  citing  the  precedent  of  the  Board  of 
Tax  Appeals,  which  has  since  become  the  Tax  Court.  In  the  meantime,  he 
urged,  the  division  into  administrative  and  judicial  sections  would  be  a 
flexible  matter.  This  flexibility  would  have  its  advantages.  It  would  avoid 
the  danger  that  an  entirely  new  set  of  administrative  courts  might  be  staffed 
with  lawyers  alone,  who  would  carry  over  with  them  the  approach  of  the 
traditional  judicial  system.  By  comparison  with  the  regular  courts,  their 
more  specialized  acquaintance  with  the  subject  matter  might  well  lead  the 
new  legal  staffs  of  administrative  courts  to  encroach  even  more  aggressively 
on  administrative  initiative. 

This  is  speculation.  But  we  may  recall  that  the  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Law  of  the  American  fiar  Association  proposed  in  1936 — without  get- 
ting the  support  of  the  Bar  Association  as  a  whole— the  creation  of  an  ad- 
ministrative court,  with  a  trial  division  of  at  least  four  sections,  to  absorb 
several  "legislative"  courts  then  in  existence  and  take  .over  their  jurisdiction. 
This  court  would  have  settled  claims  and  handled  the  revocation  or  suspen- 
sion of  licenses  and  other  regulatory  permits.  Its  appellate  division  would 
have  reviewed  the  decisions  of  the  trial  sections  on  all  issues  of  law  and 


542  THE  JUDICIAL  TEST 

fact.  The  ultimate  purpose  of  the  proposal  was  to  extend  judicial  review  to 
the  findings  of  facts  on  which  regulatory  authority  is  based. 

Political  Factors.  There  is  no  essential  reason  why  a  system  of  administra- 
tive courts  should  be  expected  to  take  over  the  administrative  functions  of 
executive  agencies  or  encroach  on  them  by  extending  the  scope  of  judicial 
review.  However,  the  administrative  courts  grew  up  on  the  Continent  in 
part  because  the  ordinary  judiciary  was  not  permitted  to  check  administra- 
tion. To  duplicate  them  here,  where  the  courts  have  been  accustomed  to 
interfering  too  much,  might  give  more  opportunity  for  such  interference. 

The  letter  of  the  law  and  judicial  methods  have  never  been  the  principal 
safeguards  of  individual  freedom,  even  in  the  courts  themselves.  The  courts 
may  have  been  more  able  to  protect  liberties  in  English-speaking  countries 
than  elsewhere  because  their  traditional  system  gave  them  more  discretion- 
ary authority  to  accomplish  the  moral  objectives  of  justice  than  Continental 
courts  were  permitted.34  On  the  other  hand,  some  of  the  strongest  restraints 
on  arbitrary  administrative  action  are  political. 

It  has  often  been  remarked  that  a  regulatory  agency  and  the  regulated 
interest  may  tend  to  work  together  very  closely.  Pressure  of  the  political 
agency  heads  on  their  subordinates  will  often  be  in  the  direction  of  prose- 
cuting only  clear  cases  of  violation  in  order  to  avoid  the  protests  and  political 
opposition  that  might  be  caused  by  questionable  ones.  The  agency  ordinar- 
ily has  a  strong  motive  for  going  easy  on  its  "constituents,"  since  it  may 
need  their  support  in  obtaining  appropriations  or  additional  legislative 
authority.  Moreover,  agencies  may  have  reason  to  fear  that  some  of  their 
regulatory  functions  will  be  taken  from  them  and  transferred  to  a  com- 
petitor. It  is  possible  that  this  fear  adds  to  their  desire  to  cultivate  the 
support  of  the  interests  they  are  regulating. 

The  agency  usually  issues  regulations  as  well  as  enforces  them,  and  in 
preparing  such  regulations  it  generally  consults  closely  with  the  interests 
concerned.  Any  unreasonable  requirement  will  certainly  cause  a  protest  to 
Congress,  which  holds  over  the  agency  the  threat  of  reduced  appropriations 
or  withdrawal  of  statutory  authority.  Thus  we  have  a  degree  of  respon- 
sibility to  the  legislature  in  the  regulation  of  economic  interests,  whether 
the  regulating  agency  is  an  independent  commission  or  an  executive  depart- 
ment, in  addition  to  the  latter's  responsibility  to  the  President.  Neither 
house  of  the  lawmaking  body  as  a  whole  can  deal  with  protests,  but  com- 
mittee hearings  give  legislators  a  much  more  effective  opportunity  to  dig 
into  the  details  of  administration.  The  main  shortcoming  of  the  existing 
system  is  that — except  in  the  event  of  disaster  or  crisis — it  puts  all  the  pres- 
sure in  the  direction  of  relaxing,  rather  than  strengthening,  the  authority 
of  the  regulatory  agency. 

84  Sec  two  articles  on  this  point  by  Pekelis,  Alexander  H.,  "Legal  Techniques  and  Po- 
litical Ideologies,"  Michigan  Law  "Review ,  1943,  Vol.  41,  p.  4  ff.,  and  "Administrative  Dis- 
cretion and  the  Rule  of  Law,"  Social  Research,  1943,  Vol.  10,  p.  1  ff. 


THE  JUDICIAL  TEST  543 

5.  CONCLUSION 

Benefits  of  Administrative  Specialization.  The  essentials  of  justice  in 
human  relations  are  eternal.  They  involve  basic  questions  of  ethics  and 
politics  which  do  not  change  with  scientific  or  industrial  development. 
In  order  to  safeguard  human  rights  and  human  dignity,  it  is  necessary  to 
have  not  only  an  elected  legislature  with  power  to  establish  the  basic  rules 
of  society,  but  also  a  judiciary  whose  concern  with  fundamental  values  will 
not  be  distorted  by  specialized  interests. 

However,  just  as  the  legislature  will  best  discharge  its  general  function 
if  it  leaves  technical  rules  to  be  established  by  responsible  administrators, 
so  the  courts  can  most  effectively  protect  human  rights  if  the  great  volume 
of  specialized  cases  is  handled  by  administrative  adjudication — subject  to 
the  power  of  the  courts  to  enforce  the  principles  of  fair  play. 

Combining  Flexibility  and  Principle.  The  role  of  government  in  mod- 
ern society  is  too  dynamic  and  too  diversified  for  us  to  attain  justice  merely 
by  conforming  to  traditional  methods.  Rigid  judicial  procedure  would  be 
intolerable  in  the  wide  fields  of  activity  in  which  administrative  agencies 
are  today  the  copilots  with  private  management. 

Here  is  one  of  the  great  challenges  to  public  administration  in  the 
future — to  organize  a  system  of  administrative  adjudication,  closely  asso- 
ciated with  the  execution  of  policy,  that  will  combine  the  virtues  of  dis- 
patch and  flexibility  with  the  degree  of  institutional  independence  necessary 
to  safeguard  individual  rights. 


CHAPTER 


24 


Personnel  Standards 


1.  RESPONSIBILITY  AND  COMPETENCE 

Ensuring  Responsive  and  Resourceful  Administration.  Responsible  pub- 
lic management  is  not  simply  attained  by  subjecting  administrative  agencies 
to  axioms  of  "government  of  laws."  It  requires  corresponding  modes  of 
administrative  behavior — a  true  service  ideology.  It  also  requires  institu- 
tional expectancies  of  technical  competence.  \^Thc  demand  for  a  high  cali- 
ber of  public  personnel  therefore  not  only  aims  at  a  working  force  of  proved 
ability  but  also  at  general  standards  of  efficiency.  Without  such  standards 
no  government  department  could  undertake  effectively  to  shoulder  its 
statutory  responsibilities?^ 

In  this  sense,  personnel  administration  provides  the  very  foundation  of 
resourceful  and  responsive  management.  The  rules  and  methods  which 
govern  the  organization  of  the  working  force  in  public  employment  occupy 
a  central  place  in  the  system  of  administrative  responsibility.  Civil  service 
commissions  and  personnel  officers  concern  themselves  with  a  large  variety 
of  highly  specialized  activities,  but  all  of  these  activities  bear  in  one  way 
or  another  upon  the  problem  of  safeguarding  the  responsible  conduct  of 
governmental  business. 

Management  and  the  Personnel  function.  As  with  comparable  func- 
tions like  budgeting  and  planning,  it  is  characteristic  of  personnel  admin- 
istration that  its  contribution  cannot  be  measured  objectively  when  it 
operates  in  the  sphere  of  its  greatest  effectiveness,  but  its  value  is  relatively 
determinable  when  it  neglects  its  most  important  function.  The  paradox 
is  simple  to  explain.  The  personnel  director  is  essentially  an  adviser  to 
management — from  the  top  executive  down  to  the  first-line  supervisor.  As 
he  performs  this  task,  either  effectively  or  poorly,  his  contribution  is  com- 
mingled with  that  of  general  management  and  therefore  it  is  not  senarately 
measurable.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  personnel  office  confines  itself  to 
its  own  operations,  it  can  boast  of  the  number  of  applicants  recruited,  of 
training  classes  held,  of  jobs  classified,  and  point  to  similar  activities  that 

544 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  545 

are  capable  of  statistical  treatment.  These  are  all  useful  and  necessary  serv- 
ices, but  such  reporting  fails  to  demonstrate  the  personnel  office's  role  in 
management  decisions. 

The  growing  significance  of  personnel  administration  results  from  the 
increase  in  the  knowledge  required  to  handle  successfully  the  human  prob- 
lems of  a  large  organization.  While  the  specific  techniques  of  personnel 
administration  are  highly  important,  they  achieve  this  importance  only  to 
the  extent  to  which  they  contribute  to  sound  working  relations  in  an  or- 
ganization. Personnel  administration  aids  the  supervisor  in  accomplishing 
the  goal  of  effective  human  relations  by  the  assistance  it  can  give  him  in 
meeting  his  responsibilities,  even  though  he  and  his  line  superiors  have 
to  set  the  substantive  objectives. 

Reformist  Background  and  Legislative  Aspirations.  An  attempt  to  de- 
scribe the  present  outlook  on  public  personnel  administration  should  not 
conceal  its  background  in  earlier  reform  movements.  It  is  only  because 
the  reformers  of  a  past  era  were  relatively  successful  that  public  personnel 
administration  has  been  able  to  advance  its  position  to  the  point  where  it 
is  being  accepted  as  one  of  the  most  important  units  on  the  level  of  top 
management. 

The  presence  of  a  merit  system  is  usually  indicated  by  the  passage  of 
legislation  providing  for  appointments  based  on  open  competitive  examina- 
tion. Such  legislation  was  enacted  by  the  federal  government  and  New  York 
State  in  1883  and  by  Massachusetts  in  1884.  Other  states,  cities,  and 
counties  have  followed  their  lead  and  accepted  the  merit  principle  in  public 
employment.1  The  astute  observer  will  note  at  times,  however,  that  while 
the  facade  furnished  by  civil  service  legislation  is  pleasing,  the  internal 
structure  beneath  has  not  always  changed.2 

Definite  progress  can  be  noted,  nonetheless.  In  the  federal  government 
a  large  area  of  employment  is  based  on  merit.  New  York  City  under 
Mayor  LaGuardia,  Los  Angeles  under  Mayor  Bowron,  and  Minnesota 
under  Governor  Stassen  are  a  few  of  many  examples  of  comparatively  ef- 
fective adherence  to  the  letter  and  spirit  of  the  merit  principle.  In  recent 
years,  one  of  the  greatest  advances  has  resulted  from  the  Social  Security 
Act,  which  provides  that  local  and  state  employees  in  services  subsidized 
by  the  federal  government  under  this  law  must  be  selected  on  the  basis  of 
open  competition. 

1Thc  period  of  greatest  activity  in  the  spread  of  the  merit  system  was  in  the  1930's, 
when  a  number  of  states  and  cities  enacted  civil  service  laws.  Various  states,  including  New 
York,  have  a  merit  system  based  on  provisions  of  the  state  constitution.  This  arrangement  is 
sometimes  preferred  since  constitutional  provisions  are  not  changed  as  easily  as  statutory 
enactments. 

2  Many  civil  service  commissions  have  funds  so  inadequate  that  no  good  selection  program 
can  be  undertaken.  The  presence  of  a  large  proportion  of  positions  exempted  from  competitive 
examinations  usually  indicates  that  patronage  still  plays  a  strong  role  in  appointments,  al- 
though there  are  also  other  more  subtle  methods  to  evade  civil  service  provisions. 


546  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

While  much  of  the  following  discussion  will  relate  to  personnel  man- 
agement and  organization,  it  may  be  stressed  that  there  is  not  as  yet 
sufficient  acceptance  by  the  people  of  the  United  States  of  the  importance 
of  good  public  management  to  justify  relaxation  of  civic  vigilance.  Much 
still  depends  on  the  endeavors  of  such  organizations  as  the  National  Civil 
Service  League  and  the  National  League  of  Women  Voters  to  extend  and 
strengthen  the  merit  rule.3  So  long  as  some  groups  favor  ineffectual  gov- 
ernment, the  merit  system  has  to  be  guarded. 

New  OutlooJ^.  The  1930's  produced  for  the  first  time  a  widespread 
awareness  of  the  fact  that  many  able  men  and  women  consider  government 
employment  useful  and  challenging  work.  It  is  obvious  that  the  public 
service  has  always  had  outstanding  employees.  But  this  was  a  matter 
of  chance,  except  in  some  specialized  fields  such  as  forest  administration 
where  government  was  a  major  employer.  Economic  conditions  in  the 
Great  Depression  and  the  marked  extension  of  public  administration  turned 
attention  to  government  as  an  attractive  career. 

While  the  movement  toward  public  employment  resulted  in  part  from 
the  lack  of  opportunities  in  private  enterprise  and  from  the  search  for 
security,  it  developed  into  a  positive  acceptance  of  the  distinct  advantages 
of  government  work  in  terms  of  its  contribution  to  the  general  welfare  and 
its  utilization  of  the  individual's  abilities.4  The  increase  in  enrollment  in 
college  and  university  courses  in  public  administration  and  the  higher 
quality  of  personnel  who  during  this  period  entered  the  government  service 
— city,  state,  and  federal — are  partial  indications  of  the  changed  situation. 

Diversity  of  Government  Employment.  Government  employment  va- 
ries sufficiently  with  time,  place,  and  occupation  to  make  generalizations 
difficult.  Yet  any  one  considering  a  career  in  government  should  be  familiar 
with  the  conditions  which  he  may  find.  Public  service  has  been  com- 
mended for  its  security  and  condemned  for  its  low  salaries.  Both  of  these 
general  assertions  are  definitely  false  in  many  specific  instances.  Private 
utilities,  banks,  insurance  companies,  and  the  large  mercantile  and  manu- 

3  Civil   service  reform  has  been  in  the  mainstream  of  good-government  movements  in 
the  United  States.     The  activity  on  this  front  began  after  the  Civil  War  and  is  still  going 
strong.    The  National  Civil  Service  Reform  League  only  recently  dropped  the  word  "Reform" 
from  its  name,  possibly  as  a  result  of  the  changed  connotation  of  the  term.     The  student 
and    the   practitioner   of   public   personnel    administration   should    know    the   history   of   civil 
service  reform.     Some  good  sources  are:  Foulke,  William  D.,  Fighting  the  Spoilsman,  New 
York:  Putnam,  1919;  United  States  Civil  Service  Commission,  A  History  of  the  Federal  Civil 
Service,  1789-1939,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1939;  and  Stewart,  Frank  M,, 
The  National  Civil  Service  Reform  League,  Austin:  University  of  Texas,  1929. 

4  The  interest  of  university  students  in  employment  opportunities  in  the  public  service  is 
indicated  by  the  Harvard  Guardian  Conference  on  the  American  Public  Service  which  was 
organized  by  a  group  of  undergraduates  at  Harvard  University.     The  publication  resulting 
from  the  conference  is  a  significant  addition  to  the  literature  of  public  administration:  Mor- 
stein  Marx,  Fritz,  ed..  Public  Management  in  the  New  Democracy,  New  York:  Harper,  1940. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  547 

facturing  establishments,  practically  speaking,  for  many  of  their  employees 
offer  as  much  security  as  does  government.  Conversely,  federal  employ- 
ment holds  forth  financial  compensation  which  for  all  but  the  two  or  three 
per  cent  in  the  higher  technical  and  administrative  positions  compares  fa- 
vorably with  that  of  private  industry.5 

For  instance,  the  top  legal  position  in  the  federal  service  carries  a  salary 
of  $15,000;  incomes  are  ten  or  twenty  times  as  large  for  some  lawyers  in 
private  practice.  On  the  other  hand,  despite  the  great  ability  of  many 
lawyers  in  the  federal  service,  there  is  no  assurance  that  most  of  them 
would  have  higher  incomes  if  they  left  the  government  for  private  practice. 
This  is  not  to  question  the  very  definite  need  for  higher  salaries,  especially 
in  local  or  state  governments,  but  rather  to  suggest  that  those  interested  in 
public  service  need  not  be  deterred  because  of  considerations  of  income. 

As  to  the  distribution  of  occupations  in  the  public  service,  it  should  not 
be  assumed  that  the  majority  of  government  employees  are  office  workers. 
A  government  employee  is  just  as  likely  to  be  a  mechanic  in  a  Navy  ship- 
yard or  an  Army  arsenal,  a  letter  carrier,  a  laborer  on  a  highway  or  a  sewer 
project,  an  inspector  of  elevators  or  livestock,  a  hospital  attendant,  a  farmer's 
adviser  on  soil  conservation  or  animal  husbandry,  or  a  laboratory  assistant. 
The  supervisors  and  administrators  are  not  expert  paper-shufflers  but  em- 
ployees directing  police  work,  the  building  of  dams,  the  running  of  insur- 
ance services,  or  the  maintenance  of  parks  or  highways.  Government  has 
many  clerks,  but  so  does  any  company  in  private  industry  which  is  interested 
in  maintaining  records  on  its  production,  its  income,  and  its  expenditures. 

2.  THE  PERSONNEL  OFFICE  IN  GOVERNMENT 

The  personnel  functions  of  the  executive  branch  of  government  are 
typically  divided  among  a  central  personnel  agency,  the  personnel  specialists 
in  each  agency,  and  the  operating  officials  and  supervisors.  This  division 
of  functions  has  inevitably  led  to  fights  for  control.  The  central  personnel 
agency,  usually  called  the  civil  service  commission,  tends  to  guard  its  powers 
and  look  with  suspicion  upon  efforts  of  the  operating  agencies  to  assume 
greater  responsibilities.  Agency  personnel  specialists,  while  on  the  one 
hand  opposing  the  central  personnel  agency,  on  the  other  hand  look  askance 
at  the  efforts  of  line  officials  to  obtain  independence  from  personnel  controls. 
The  supervisors  and  even  the  operating  executives  frequently  have  not  much 
use  for  either  of  the  others.  Yet  it  is  a  reasonable  assumption  that  each  of 

15  This  statement  is  not  meant  to  imply  that  government  salaries  are  as  high  as  those 
in  private  industry  on  the  basis  of  comparison  of  duties  and  responsibilities,  especially  in  the 
upper  ranges.  But  there  are  not  so  many  high-paying  jobs  in  industry,  and  the  underpaid 
government  employee  may  not  be  able  to  obtain  a  higher  salary  in  industry  because  of  lack 
of  opportunity.  City  and  state  governments,  in  general,  pay  much  less  than  corresponding 
positions  in  private  industrv. 


548  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

the  three  elements  in  the  personnel  picture  has  an  important  role,  and  that 
light  shed  on  their  respective  responsibilities  will  help  avoid  the  heat  of  or- 
ganizational friction. 

Central  Personnel  Agencies.  No  central  personnel  agency  can  hope  to 
be  popular  always  or  with  every  one.  Under  the  laws  and  constitutional 
provisions  affecting  its  work,  it  must  try  to  meet  almost  irreconcilable  re- 
quirements.6 A  single  agency  cannot  administer  laws  relating  in  general 
terms  to  veterans  preference,  apportionment,  appointment  by  open  com- 
petition, pay  increases  within  grade,  and  classification  and  compensation 
based  on  evaluation  of  duties,  and  at  the  same  time  satisfy  the  specific  re- 
cruitment, promotion,  and  classification  needs  of  thousands  of  supervisors 
in  individual  personnel  actions.7  The  best  central  personnel  agencies  rec- 
ognize the  duality  of  responsibilities  and  evaluate  each  of  their  actions  in 
the  light  of  both  responsibilities.  The  major  attacks  on  central  personnel 
agencies  have  arisen  when  one  or  the  other  responsibility  has  been  used  as 
the  sole  basis  for  operation.  Attempting  rigidly  to  enforce  general  rules  of 
statutory  personnel  policy  has  resulted  in  criticism  from  the  operating 
agencies  of  interference  in  good  management.  Meeting  fully  even  the 
legitimate  desires  of  top  administrators  and  line  executives  has  resulted  in 
public  condemnations  for  seeming  violations  of  laws  and  regulations. 

The  relationship  of  the  central  personnel  agency  to  the  chief  executive 
—whether  he  be  mayor,  governor,  or  President— is  a  vital  factor  in  its  suc- 
cess. Close  contact  is  fundamental  to  the  establishment  of  satisfactory 
working  connections  with  line  agencies  and  to  obtaining  adequate  funds 
with  which  to  operate.  In  order  to  strengthen  this  relationship,  there  has 
arisen  during  recent  years  a  movement  away  from  independent  civil  service 
commissions  with  administrative  responsibilities  toward  single-headed  per- 
sonnel departments  assisted  by  an  advisory  committee  with  rule-making 
and  review  functions  but  no  operating  authority.  The  new  general  prin- 
ciple was  strongly  advocated  by  President  Franklin  D.  Roosevelt's  Commit- 
tee on  Administrative  Management  which  recommended,  in  addition  to 

«Mosher,  William  E.  and  Kingsley,  J.  Donald,  Public  Personnel  Administration,  chs. 
4,  5,  and  6,  New  York:  Harper,  rev.  ed.,  1941,  contains  an  excellent  discussion  of  the  func- 
tions and  organizational  problems  of  central  personnel  agencies.  This  is  the  leading  textbook 
on  the  subject.  Other  good  introductions  are:  "Improved  Personnel  in  Government  Service," 
Annals  of  the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1937,  Vol.  189;  Readings  in 
Public  Personnel  Administration,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1942;  and  Reeves,  Floyd 
W.  and  David,  Paul  T.,  Personnel  Administration  in  the  federal  Service,  Washington:  Gov- 
ernment Printing  Office,  1937,  one  of  the  special  studies  for  the  President's  Committee  on 
Administrative  Management. 

7  Cf.  White,  Leonard  D.,  ed.,  Civil  Service  In  Wartime,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago, 
J945,  which  indicates  on  the  whole  that  civil  service  commissions  can,  if  necessary,  meet  the 
k-ecruiting  needs  even  of  wartime  government  if  they  transfer  a  large  part  of  the  initiative 
for  recruitment  to  the  line  agencies.  See  also  above  Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administra- 
tion," sec.  3,  "Training  for  Public  Adminsitration." 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  549 

the  abolition  of  the  three-member  commission,  that  the  central  personnel 
agency  be  made  part  of  the  new  Executive  Office  of  the  President.8 

Congressional  opposition  to  this  principle  was  based  on  the  role  of  the 
Civil  Service  Commission  as  a  control  agency,  as  distinguished  from  the 
view  of  the  President's  Committee,  which  stressed  the  services  that  a  per- 
sonnel agency  should  offer  to  operating  officials.  So  an  intermediary  ar- 
rangement was  made:  the  commission  was  maintained,  but  a  Liaison  Officer 
for  Personnel  Management  was  established  as  part  of  the  President's 
immediate  staff.  Some  states,  however,  such  as  Michigan,  Connecticut,  and 
Minnesota,  have  in  effect  followed  the  recommendations  of  the  President's 
Committee.  While  this  conflict  between  congressional  and  presidential 
views  is  symbolic  of  the  dualism  of  responsibilities  of  the  central  personnel 
agency,  there  is  thus  far  no  conclusive  evidence  that  the  device  of  the  single- 
headed  personnel  department  has  resulted  in  a  definite  shift  of  emphasis 
between  control  and  service  responsibilities. 

Wording  Relationships.  There  is  an  unfortunate  gap  between  the  central 
personnel  and  budget  agencies  in  most  governmental  units  whereas  their 
functions  reveal  the  need  for  effective  coordination.  In  Connecticut,  the 
budget  and  personnel  functions  are  more  closely  linked  than  in  most  juris- 
dictions, partly  as  a  result  of  having  the  heads  of  both  functions  report 
to  the  Commissioner  of  Finance  and  Control  rather  than  independently  to 
the  governor.  This  may  indicate  that  the  United  States  Civil  Service  Com- 
mission, if  made  part  of  the  Executive  Office  of  the  President  and  placed 
under  a  head  of  that  office  who  would  also  direct  the  budget  function, 
could  achieve  a  closer  and  more  permanent  relationship  with  the  Bureau  of 
the  Budget  than  is  possible  on  the  present  basis  of  informal  agreements  and 
mutual  interests.  Where  there  is  a  gap  between  the  two  functions,  the  per- 
sonnel agency  is  prone  to  accuse  the  budget  office  of  failing  to  recognize 
the  human  problems  of  administration  while  the  budgeteers  may  decry  the 
financial  cost  of  proposed  personnel  policies. 

The  expansion  of  the  functions  of  central  personnel  agencies,  especially 
during  the  past  twenty-five  years,  makes  it  evident  that  a  civil  service  com- 
mission's work  can  be  ruinous  to  good  administration  unless  its  functions 
are  properly  administered.0  When  appointments  were  its  main  task,  good 
management  could  alleviate  mistakes  made.  The  entrance  of  civil  service 
commissions  into  such  areas  as  classification,  compensation,  within-grade 
salary  increases,  service  ratings,  personnel  utilization,  and  appeals  from 
discharges  has  given  them  an  outstanding  opportunity  to  assist  in  the  im- 

8  The  most  extended  discussion  of  this  important  organizational  problem  is  to  be  found 
in    Reeves   and    David,    op.   cit.   above   note   6.   The   usual   civil    service   commission   in   the 
United  States  is  a  three-member,  bipartisan  board  appointed  by  the  chief  executive  with  the 
consent  of  the  upper  chamber  of  the  legislature,  the  members  serving  overlapping  terms.    Cf. 
also  above  Ch.  8,  "The  Chief  Executive,"  sec.  5,  "Arms  of  Modern  Management." 

9  For  discussion  of  what  these  functions  should  be,  see  Hubbard,  Henry  F.,  "Elements 
of  a  Comprehensive  Personnel  Program,"  Public  Personnel  Review,  1940,  Vol.  1,  pp.  1-17. 


550  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

provement  of  public  administration  and  at  the  same  time  made  inefficiency 
on  their  part  a  heavy  burden  which  even  the  most  competent  administrators 
cannot  carry.  The  expansion  of  personnel  activities  thus  is  a  great  challenge. 
Administering  its  program  with  full  recognition  of  management  problems, 
the  civil  service  commission  can  help  raise  administration  to  a  high  plane; 
conversely,  its  work  can  lead  to  the  condemnation  of  all  personnel  activities, 
both  good  and  bad. 

Of  course,  the  personnel  agency  is  subject  to  extraneous  influences. 
The  pressure  groups  in  civil  service  administration  are  easily  identified.10 
There  is  that  part  of  the  public  which  is  interested  in  government  employ- 
ment, whose  most  frequent  complaints  are  directed  at  the  nature  of  the 
examinations  used — some  favoring  one  type,  some  another,  based  largely 
on  self-interest.  There  are  those  entitled  to  veterans  preference,  who  are 
anxious  that  this  preference  be  observed  faithfully.11  There  are  the  civic 
groups,  who  either  as  taxpayers  or  as  citizens  concerned  with  the  general 
welfare  are  anxious  that  civil  service  commissions  withstand  other  pressures, 
whether  from  the  chief  executive,  the  legislature,  or  special-interest  groups, 
including  government  employees  or  prospective  employees.  There  are  the 
various  technical  and  professional  bodies  interested  in  higher  qualification 
standards  and  higher  classification  grades  in  their  special  fields.  And  there 
are  the  legislators,  interested  in  consideration  of  their  constituents'  problems 
and  alert,  at  times,  to  correct  apparent  wrong-doing  in  the  executive  branch 
of  government. 

Departmental  Personnel  Offices.  The  central  personnel  agency  cannot 
and,  as  a  practical  matter,  should  not  attempt  to  carry  out  all  specialized  per- 
sonnel functions  by  itself.  Such  an  attempt  would  lead  to  self-destruction. 
In  any  large  jurisdiction,  the  central  agency  is  too  far  removed  from  im- 
mediate operating  problems  to  make  this  virtual  monopoly  desirable. 

To  provide  those  personnel  services  which  a  central  personnel  agency 
cannot  perform  and  to  bring  personnel  operations  closer  to  the  operating 
officials  who  need  assistance,  departmental  personnel  offices  have  been  estab- 
lished.12 In  the  case  of  large  federal  agencies,  bureau  and  regional  personnel 
offices  have  also  been  set  up.  As  was  suggested  previously,  the  central 
personnel  agency  can  look  on  these  offices  either  as  contenders  for  power  or 
as  valuable  allies  in  making  the  personnel  function  effective. 

10  The  best  discussion  of  this  and  related  subjects  is  to  be  found  in  Public  Relations  of 
Public  Personnel  Agencies,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1941. 

11  Veterans  preference  can  only  be  justified  by  a  theory  that  public  employment  should 
be  used  for  patriotic  purposes;  it  cannot  be  justified  either  on  the  basis  of  merit-system  selec- 
tion or  the  best  administration  of  the  public  services.    Cf.  Miller,  John  F.,  "Veterans  Prefer- 
ence in  the  Public  Service,"  in  Friedrich,  Carl  J.  and  Others,  Problems  of  the  American  Public 
Service,  New  York:  McGraw-Hill,  1935. 

12  There  is  no  adequate  publication  on  the  functions  and  administrative  problems  of  a 
departmental  personnel  office.    Some  discussion  of  this  subject  is  to  be  found  in  Altmcycr, 
A.  J.,  "The  Scope  of  Departmental  Personnel  Activities,"  Annals  of  the  American  Academy 
of  Political  and  Social  Science,  1937,  Vol.  189,  pp.  188-191. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  551 

Too  often,  the  situation  has  degenerated  into  open  conflict,  with  the 
agency  personnel  office  stressing  the  specific  needs  of  its  department,  while 
the  central  agency  has  emphasized  the  over-all  governmental  viewpoint  and 
legislative  and  procedural  limitations.  As  a  result,  too  much  of  the  time 
of  the  departmental  personnel  office  is  sometimes  spent  in  planning  hov; 
to  outmaneuver  the  central  agency.  What  this  differentiation  of  functions 
requires  is  administrative  skill  and  professional  competence  on  both  sides. 
Since  1939,  the  Council  of  Personnel  Administration  in  the  federal  govern- 
ment has  proved  to  be  an  excellent  device  for  helping  to  reconcile  the  two 
conflicting  forces  by  providing  a  formal  method  for  bringing  together  de- 
partmental personnel  officers  and  Civil  Service  Commission  representatives. 

The  creation  of  departmental  personnel  staffs  is  mainly  a  development 
of  the  1930's,  but  the  personnel  office  of  the  United  States  Department  of 
Agriculture  was  set  up  in  the  1920's  shortly  after  the  passage  of  the  Classi- 
fication Act  of  1923.  Executive  Order  No.  7916  of  June  24,  1938,  required 
each  federal  agency  to  establish  such  offices.  They  grew  out  of  the  clerical 
functions  previously  performed  by  departmental  chief  clerks  in  such  matters 
as  payroll  preparation  and  recording  of  leave.13  By  and  large,  they  have 
not  been  extensively  developed  in  local  or  state  governments,  although  the 
Department  of  Water  and  Power  in  the  city  of  Los  Angeles  has  long  had 
such  an  office  and  some  steps  in  this  direction  have  been  taken  in  New 
York  City  and  elsewhere.  In  general,  any  governmental  agency  interested 
in  a  full-fledged  personnel  program  can  justify  having  at  least  one  full-time 
professional  personnel  assistant,  even  when  its  total  roster  is  as  low  as  two 
hundred. 

No  matter  what  the  type  of  organization  may  be,  the  fundamental  per- 
sonnel needs  remain  the  same,  although  emphasis  varies  with  time  and 
administrative  circumstances.  Classification  of  positions  according  to  simi- 
larity of  duties  is  basic  to  good  administration  and  other  personnel  functions. 
The  employment  process,  which  encompasses  recruitment,  examination, 
selection,  and  placement,  has  long  been  considered  the  core  of  personnel 
administration.  Equally  important  is  the  work  involved  in  individual  and 
group  training  and  in  employee  relations.  In  some  organizations,  such  as 
public  transportation  and  utilities  systems,  safety  engineering  is  a  pertinent 
activity. 

Relations  with  Operating  Officials.  The  ultimate  test  of  the  effectiveness 
of  any  personnel  office,  whether  central  or  departmental,  is  the  extent  to 
which  it  implements  the  work  of  the  operating  official.  In  other  words, 
personnel  administration  is  the  means  whereby  the  line  official  obtains 
specialized  assistance  to  help  him  carry  out  his  functions.  The  first  task 

13  The  existence  of  a  personnel  office  is  not  a  definite  indication  that  the  office  is  pro- 
viding professional  rather  than  clerical  personnel  services  to  a  department.  Too  often  ex- 
pertness  in  regulations  is  substituted  for  skill  in  recruitment,  placement,  training,  and  em- 
ployee relations. 


552  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

of  the  personnel  specialist  is  to  aid  the  operating  official  in  identifying  and 
meeting  his  employee  problems.14  Handling  of  training  and  employee  re- 
lations matters,  setting  qualification  standards,  and  determining  job  duties  is 
the  work  of  the  supervisor  and  not  that  of  the  personnel  specialist.  When 
the  latter  assists  on  these  problems,  he  can  do  so  only  at  the  request  of  the 
supervisor.  To  the  greatest  extent  possible,  the  supervisor  should  be  trained 
so  that  he  can  perform  his  own  duties  efficiently. 

It  would  be  easy  for  the  personnel  officer  merely  to  exercise  control  and 
not  to  attempt  to  enlighten  or  persuade.  It  would  be  simple  to  dismiss 
a  personnel  request  from  a  supervisor  as  improper  and  require  him  to 
justify  each  action  in  detail.  But  it  is  obvious  that  this  approach  would 
lead  nowhere.  The  opposite  and  constructive  approach  compels  the  per- 
sonnel officer  to  develop  his  techniques  so  that  any  suggestions  made  to 
the  supervisor  are  based  on  convincing  reasons. 

It  should  not  be  necessary  to  belabor  this  point,  but  much  of  the  chief 
criticism  of  personnel  administration  is  related  to  it.  Starting  out  with  the 
point  of  view  of  reformers  anxious  to  defeat  the  spoilsmen,  personnel  ad- 
ministration has  yet  to  learn  that  it  is  now  part  of  management,  and  not 
divorced  from  it.  It  has  yet  to  appreciate  that  its  justification  lies  not  in 
aloofness  but  in  its  contribution  to  management.15 

Qualifications  for  Personnel  Worf(.  Personnel  administration  is  one  of 
the  social  sciences,  and  its  work  therefore  requires  knowledge  of  human 
behavior  and  ability  in  personal  relations.  Since  it  is  also  part  of  manage- 
ment, it  calls  for  a  thorough  understanding  of  all  management  problems, 
including  organization,  public  relations,  and  coordination.  In  addition,  the 
personnel  specialist,  to  be  able  to  help  the  line  official,  must  know  the  spe- 
cific techniques  of  training,  placement,  employee  relations,  classification, 
and  recruitment. 

The  production  engineer  has  his  knowledge  of  machines  and  manufac- 
turing methods,  the  physician  his  knowledge  of  human  ailments  and  meth- 
ods of  treatment.  The  personnel  specialist  has  to  be  acquainted  with  the 
body  of  knowledge  that  has  been  developed  in  his  field.  Without  it  he  merely 
brings  to  the  solution  of  a  problem  a  vague  desire  to  do  well  which,  at  best, 
is  offensive  to  the  supervisors.  In  addition  to  his  knowledge  of  techniques, 
however,  he  has  to  be  skilled  in  their  application.  He  is  not  an  automobile 
mechanic  treating  an  inanimate  car  but  a  responsible  agent  counseling  em- 
ployees, interviewing  applicants  for  employment,  and  advising  management. 

14  The  most  realistic  study  of  this  and  related  areas  of  administration  is  presented  in 
Meriam,   Lewis,   Public  Personnel  Problems  from   the  Standpoint  of  the   Operating   Officer, 
Washington:  Brookings  Institution,  1938.   Cf.  also  above  Ch.  18,  "The  Tasks  of  Middle  Man- 
agement," and  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision." 

15  For  a  comparison  of  public  and  industrial  personnel  administration,  see  Graham,  George 
A.,  "Personnel  Practices  in  Business  and  Governmental  Organizations,"  op.  cit.  above  note  11, 
pp.  337-427. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  553 

3.  CLASSIFICATION  AND  COMPENSATION 

Characteristics  of  Classification.  The  introduction  of  classification  into 
the  field  of  public  personnel  administration  has  provided  a  tool  which,  while 
not  yet  perfected,  is  of  basic  importance  to  other  processes  such  as  employ- 
ment, examination,  training,  service  rating,  salary  determination,  budgeting, 
and  organizational  planning.10  The  first  classification  plan  in  the  public 
service  which  approached  present-day  standards  was  developed  in  the  city 
of  Chicago  shortly  before  World  War  I.  The  federal  government's  classi- 
fication program  was  adopted  by  Congress  in  1923.  A  substantial  number 
of  city  and  state  governments  have  made  progress  in  these  programs  since 
that  time.  It  is  now  generally  accepted  practice  for  a  local  or  state  govern- 
ment which  enacts  a  civil  service  law  to  begin  immediately  with  the  prepa- 
ration of  a  classification  plan. 

By  classification  is  meant  the  grouping  of  positions  on  the  basis  of  simi- 
larity of  duties  and  qualification  requirements.  Each  such  group,  which  may 
include  from  one  to  a  thousand  or  more  positions,  is  called  a  "class"  and 
each  class  has  an  appropriate  designation.  Classes  are  sometimes  arranged 
in  series — a  graded  hierarchy  of  classes  in  the  same  occupational  field  with 
the  lowest  class  having  the  simplest  duties  and  the  highest  the  most  complex 
tasks. 

Grouping  positions  into  classes  offers  a  time-saving  device  which  is  of 
immeasurable  benefit  to  other  administrative  processes.  A  state  or  city  might 
have  ten  thousand  positions  but  only  six  hundred  classes.  This  means  that  it 
would  require  only  six  hundred  examination  registers  to  meet  all  of  its  em- 
ployment needs,  not  ten  thousand.  The  budget  officer  would  not  have  to 
investigate  each  position  in  each  department  to  determine  whether  compar- 
able salaries  are  involved  in  budget  requests  from  different  departments, 
since  the  titles  of  the  positions  would  indicate  whether  the  duties  are  com- 
parable. The  training  specialist  would  know,  without  having  to  make  an 
independent  investigation,  which  departments  have  employees  who  should 
be  included  in  a  given  training  program. 

Specifications  are  usually  prepared  in  connection  with  the  development 
of  classification  plans.  These  specifications  furnish  for  each  class  a  class 
title,  a  statement  of  duties,  and  a  statement  of  appropriate  qualifications. 
The  statements  provide  a  guide  as  to  which  class  each  position  should  be 
allocated  to,  the  nature  of  the  examination  that  should  be  prepared  for  re- 
cruitment, and  the  salary  that  should  be  paid  for  employees  performing 
the  duties  described  in  the  specification. 

While  these  are  some  of  the  major  purposes  that  class  specifications  are 
designed  to  fulfill,  in  actual  practice  they  usually  fall  short  of  the  goal.  Too 
frequently  the  specifications  are  prepared  primarily  from  the  point  of  view 

10  The  most  thorough  exposition  of  this  subject  is  offered  in  Position-Clasfification  in  tkc 
Public  Service,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1941. 


554  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

of  the  classification  technician,  and  do  not  meet  the  needs  of  the  examina- 
tion and  training  specialists.  As  a  result,  the  specialists  in  examination  and 
training  duplicate  the  previous  investigation  of  positions  by  the  classification 
staff.  Extensive  participation  by  examination  and  training  specialists  in 
the  planning  and  formulation  of  classification  plans  helps  to  reduce  such 
duplication. 

Keeping  Classification  Up-To-Date.  However,  positions  in  any  organi- 
zation are  always  in  a  state  of  flux.  Rapid  changes  in  duties  often  result 
from  turnover  so  that  the  old  specification  no  longer  accurately  describes 
the  new  duties.  Addition  to  or  subtraction  from  the  functions  of  an  organi- 
zation inevitably  alters  the  composition  of  positions.  A  new  administrator 
carries  out  changes  which  are  sometimes  not  reflected  in  the  organization 
chart  but  which  affect  the  duties  of  positions.  An  increase  or  decrease  in 
appropriations  brings  with  it  a  reallocation  of  duties  among  positions.  Such 
changes,  constantly  occurring  in  any  organization,  make  necessary  a  day-by- 
day  administration  of  the  classification  plan  in  order  to  keep  it  up-to-date. 

Failure  to  recognize  this  need  has  been  frequent  and  disastrous.  It  is 
as  if  the  blueprints  for  a  1938  automobile  were  used  to  produce  today's 
model. 

To  overcome  this  condition,  a  classification  staff  is  needed  that  can,  by 
working  with  the  various  units  of  the  organization,  keep  abreast  of  posi- 
tion changes  and  make  the  necessary  revision.  This  may  be  done  by  chang- 
ing positions  from  one  class  to  another  or  by  establishing  new  classes.  The 
necessary  information  is  usually  obtained  by  requiring  a  new  description  of 
a  position  whenever  an  appointment  is  proposed  or  a  promotion  recom- 
mended; or  by  means  of  periodic  surveys  of  limited  numbers  of  positions, 
on  either  an  occupational  or  an  organizational  basis. 

General  Overview  Versus  Special  Considerations.  In  the  federal  service 
particularly,  and  to  some  extent  in  state  and  local  government,  the  classi- 
fication process  has  been  at  times  a  source  of  mystery  and  frustration  to  op- 
erating officials,  and  at  other  times  a  game  which  one  tries  to  win  by  evasion 
and  misrepresentation.  The  reasons  are  obvious.  The  classification  specialist 
attempts  to  bring  order  out  of  chaos.  To  emphasize  the  common  character- 
istics of  positions  included  in  a  class,  he  tends  to  gloss  over  those  individual 
differences  in  positions  which  destroy  the  symmetry  of  his  work.  Inevitably, 
this  means  inadequate  recognition  of  the  relative  uniqueness  of  some  posi- 
tions. Furthermore,  the  classification  specialist  looks  at  the  total  structure  of 
the  government  jurisdiction,  whereas  the  operating  official  is  only  conscious 
of  the  positions  immediately  under  his  supervision  or  under  that  of  col- 
leagues close  by.  Finally,  despite  some  valiant  efforts,  operating  officials  have 
not  yet  been  fully  informed  as  to  how  classification  operates. 

This  educational  task  is  now  recognized  as  essential.  By  means  of  confer- 
ences and  written  materials  prepared  specially  for  supervisors,  some  progress 
is  being  made.  In  the  federal  service,  however,  inflexibilities  are  produced  by 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  555 

the  need  for  congressional  approval  of  changes  in  grades  in  the  classification 
plan.  It  is  therefore  improbable  that  frustration  of  management  through  the 
classification  plan  can  soon  be  completely  overcome.  Administrative  experi- 
ence during  World  War  II,  fortunately,  has  shown  that  full  cooperation 
between  the  United  States  Civil  Service  Commission  and  the  line  agencies 
at  least  can  mitigate  the  more  serious  rigidities. 

In  the  best  administration  of  a  classification  plan,  full  weight  is  given 
to  its  close  relationship  with  organizational  planning.  At  least  partly  be- 
cause of  the  necessary  tie  between  these  two  administrative  services,  the 
Tennessee  Valley  Authority  and  the  United  States  Department  of  Agricul- 
ture have  the  organizational  planning  unit  as  part  of  the  personnel  office, 
while  in  the  United  Nations  Relief  and  Rehabilitation  Administration  classi- 
fication was  removed  from  the  personnel  division  and  made  part  of  organi- 
zational analysis.  In  any  case,  no  matter  what  structural  arrangements  are 
in  effect,  it  is  generally  considered  desirable  to  associate  surveys  for  organi- 
zational planning  with  those  for  classification  purposes  so  that  duplicate 
inquiries  can  be  avoided  and  the  fullest  use  made  by  both  groups  of  the 
information  developed  by  each.  Review  by  classification  staffs  of  individual 
position  descriptions  often  reveals  organizational  defects  which  should  be 
corrected  through  joint  action  by  management  and  organizational-planning 
specialists. 

Classification  and  the  Career  Service.  The  implications  of  a  classification 
plan  for  a  career  service  and  for  the  total  personnel  program  are  often  over- 
looked. A  good  classification  plan  can  be  compared  with  a  tree  with  a  strong 
trunk,  a  few  main  branches  extending  from  the  trunk  near  the  ground,  and 
with  proliferation  becoming  more  evident  the  higher  one  goes.  Similarly 
with  a  classification  plan.  The  number  of  classes  designed  for  original  re- 
cruitment—the trunk  and  the  main  branches—should  be  kept  to  a  minimum 
and  be  related  to  the  educational  system  so  that,  for  example,  entrance  classes 
arc  tied  in  with  high-school  graduation,  college  graduation,  and  graduate- 
and  professional-school  training.  A  large  number  of  special  classes  beyond 
these  entrance  classes  would  not,  therefore,  interfere  with  the  recruitment  of 
the  best  students  because  of  their  lack  of  experience.  Nor  would  it  throw 
a  heavy  burden  on  the  examining  process  by  unduly  multiplying  the  num- 
ber of  open  competitive  examinations  which  would  have  to  be  administered. 

One  of  the  most  significant  technical  problems  in  the  field  of  classifica- 
tion relates  to  the  need  for  an  understandable  presentation  of  the  differences 
between  classes  within  the  same  occupational  series  and  between  series.  Too 
often,  class  specifications  have  used  vague  terminology  in  attempting  to 
establish  this  distinction.  In  consequence,  a  position  as  statistician  might  be 
in  one  class  if  the  statistician  worked  in  a  small  agency  but  in  a  higher  grade 
if  the  agency  were  larger.  It  is  true  that  semantic  difficulties  occur  in  other 
fields  besides  classification,  but  much  of  the  mystery  of  classification  to  both 
management  and  employees  would  be  eliminated  by  clearer  descriptions  of 


556  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

class  differences.  In  order  to  solve  this  problem,  some  class  specifications 
prepared  in  the  last  few  years  have  included  a  section  on  "distinguishing 
features  of  the  work,"  thus  emphasizing  the  differences  between  closely 
related  classes. 

The  main  misunderstandings  in  the  field  of  classification  arise  from  a 
confusion  of  the  position  that  is  to  be  classified  with  the  employee  doing  the 
job.  The  classification  technician  attempts  to  allocate  a  position  to  a  class, 
whether  the  position  is  occupied  or  vacant.  He  is  concerned  with  the  duties 
and  responsibilities  that  have  been  assigned  by  management  to  that  position, 
and,  if  the  position  is  occupied,  are  being  performed  in  it.  He  is  not  con- 
cerned with  the  individual  employee's  qualifications  for  the  purpose  of 
determining  how  well  the  job  is  done  or  whether  the  employee  could  as- 
sume additional  responsibilities.  In  other  words,  the  employee  might  be  a 
certified  public  accountant  and  yet  be  performing  duties  which  require  only 
the  knowledge  and  skill  of  a  graduate  of  a  commercial  high-school  book- 
keeping course.  Conversely,  if  the  employee  has  had  only  bookkeeping 
training  but  is  performing  the  duties  of  a  highly  skilled  accountant,  the 
position  would  be  allocated  on  the  basis  of  the  duties  only.  Failure  to  follow 
this  principle  will  result  in  gross  inequities,  either  in  favor  or  to  the  dis- 
advantage of  the  interests  of  certain  employees. 

Compensation.  The  principal  problem  in  the  establishment  of  a  com- 
pensation plan  is  the  lack  of  a  well-defined  wage  theory  for  the  public  serv- 
ice.17 Lacking  such  a  theory,  those  responsible  for  the  preparation  of  a  com- 
pensation plan  have  floundered  among  various  improvised  conceptions.  Not 
by  the  process  of  clear  formulation  but  by  rationalization  from  practices  that 
seem  prevalent,  wage-setting  for  per-annum  employees  in  the  public  service 
appears  to  be  generally  based  on  the  minimum  rate  necessary  to  obtain  quali- 
fied employees.  In  brief,  government  has  not  attempted  to  set  a  high  rate 
for  private  industry  to  emulate  but  has  more  usually  adopted  a  rate  which 
is  not  as  low  as  the  lowest-paying  rate  in  industry  nor  as  high  as  the 
highest. 

In  contrast  with  the  practices  controlling  salaries  of  government  em- 
ployees paid  on  an  annual  basis,  it  is  customary  in  the  public  service  for  the 
trades,  labor,  and  other  per-diem  positions  to  be  compensated  at  rates  cor- 
responding to  the  highest  in  private  industry.  One  factor  that  accounts  for 
this  difference  between  per-diem  and  per-annum  employees  is  that  the  work 
of  per-diem  public  employees  tends  to  be  more  closely  comparable  to  that 
performed  in  private  industry  than  the  duties  of  the  white-collar  civil  serv- 
ant When  one  union  serves  workers  in  both  industry  and  government, 
there  is  obviously  pressure  toward  reducing  the  differences  between  the  two 
sets  of  pay  scales. 

17  For  a  discussion  of  the  problems  of  compensation  in  the  public  service,  see  Richey,  Carl 
L.,  "Determining  Pay  Policy,"  pp.  44-48,  and  Baruch,  Ismar,  "Surveying  Prevailing  Salary 
Rates,"  pp.  49-62,  Readings,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  6. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  557 

The  compensation  plan  needs  to  be  kept  as  current  as  the  classification 
plan,  although  classification  requires  day-by-day  review  while  the  influences 
affecting  the  compensation  plan  tend  to  change  more  slowly.  Increases  and 
decreases  in  costs  of  living  and  changes  in  the  demand-and-supply  situation 
in  specific  occupations  make  desirable  a  periodic  review,  probably  on  an 
annual  basis,  of  the  salary  rates  which  have  been  established.  The  city  of 
St.  Paul  was  the  leader  in  tying  the  compensation  plan  into  a  cost-of-living 
index  and  providing  for  changes  in  compensation  based  on  changes  in  the 
index.  Other  communities  have  followed  this  lead.  The  plan,  if  adopted 
with  the  full  approval  of  the  legislature,  the  chief  executive,  and  the  em- 
ployees, is  of  substantial  benefit  in  reducing  wrangling  and  bitter  disputes 
over  wages.  The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  holds  an  annual  joint  con- 
ference of  management  and  labor  to  discuss  changes  needed  in  the  wages' 
for  trades  positions,  based  on  data  collected  jointly. 

The  usual  compensation  plan  in  the  public  service  for  per-annum  posi- 
tions provides  for  a  minimum  and  a  maximum  rate  and  intermediate  rates. 
One  of  the  most  contentious  issues  in  personnel  and  budget  administration 
arises  in  connection  with  methods  for  making  increases  between  the  mini- 
mum and  the  maximum — that  is,  in-grade  increases.  In  the  past,  and  still 
current  in  some  places,  such  increases  have  been  made  on  an  unsystematic 
basis,  often  as  a  result  of  chance  availability  of  funds  or  to  reward  a  par- 
ticular individual.  To  overcome  this  unsatisfactory  condition,  some  govern- 
ment units — such  as  the  city  and  the  state  of  New  York,  the  city  of  Los 
Angeles,  and  the  federal  government — provide  automatic  in-grade  salary 
increases.  In  the  federal  service,  these  increases  are  based  on  period  of 
service  and  efficiency,  and  provision  is  made  for  an  extra  increase  for 
superior  accomplishment.  Formal  plans  for  in-grade  increases  are  appar- 
ently far  superior  to  the  previous  haphazard  methods. 

By  and  large,  the  compensation  to  be  paid  for  a  class  of  positions  is  sub- 
ject to  legislative  action.  This  control  of  specifics  has  had  a  deleterious  effect 
on  public  administration.  It  has  resulted  in  loss  of  competent  personnel  in 
periods  of  rising  wages  because  of  the  rigidity  of  legislative  determination. 
It  has  produced  evasions  in  the  administration  of  classification,  such  as 
reclassification  of  positions  in  order  to  obtain  more  money  for  a  position, 
since  the  salary  could  not  be  changed  to  meet  altered  general  conditions.  It 
has  also  injected  political  considerations  into  the  administrative  process.  It 
would  seem  desirable  for  the  legislature  to  exercise  its  control  by  review  of 
budget  estimates  rather  than  by  review  of  the  salary  ranges  for  individual 
classes  or  series  of  positions. 

4.  EMPLOYMENT 

Implications  of  the  Career  Idea.  Employment  practices  and  standards 
establish  the  "tone"  of  an  organization.  We  can  compare,  in  private  indus- 
try, the  sophisticated  personnel  of  the  advertising  agencies  and  the  staid 


538  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

staff  of  financial  institutions,  the  hurry  of  the  newspaper  room  and  the 
hushed  atmosphere  of  the  corporation  lawyer's  office.  Organizations  as  old 
as  most  government  agencies  reflect  differences  in  personnel  as  a  result  of 
variety  in  function,  in  standards  used  at  the  time  each  group  was  hired,  and 
in  age  distribution.  The  bright  young  economists  engaged  in  monetary  re- 
search in  the  Treasury  Department  are  different  in  type  from  the  experts 
in  the  same  department's  Bureau  of  Accounts.  The  recently  recruited  stenog- 
rapher fresh  from  school  is  different  from  the  secretary  who  has  been  in  the 
organization  thirty  years.  The  Ph.D.  just  hired  for  biological  research  is 
different  from  his  colleague  who  started  out  as  a  laboratory  assistant  after 
graduation  from  high  school  and  advanced  to  the  lower  grades  in  the 
professional  service. 

These  observations  make  plain  that  the  setting  of  employment  standards 
is  part  of  top-management  policy  and  not  to  be  dissociated  from  it. 
The  objectives  stated  by  the  chief  executive,  whether  in  terms  of  a  "return 
to  normalcy"  or  a  dynamic  program  which  stresses  that  "there  is  nothing 
to  fear  except  fear  itself,"  must  underlie  employment  standards.  There  was 
not  much  point  in  bringing  into  the  government  progressive  minds  when 
government  was  viewed  as  a  negative,  primarily  regulating  institution.  On 
the  other  hand,  unimaginative  technical  competence  is  not  of  much  help 
to  a  chief  executive  interested  in  blazing  new  trails.  It  is  the  function  of  the 
chief  executive  to  seek  response  from  the  legislature  if  his  objectives  are  not 
theirs;  it  is  the  function  of  the  employees  of  the  executive  branch  to  carry 
out  the  chief  executive's  goals  under  the  laws.  Attacks  by  Congressmen  on 
appointments  in  the  executive  branch  during  the  presidency  of  Franklin  D. 
Roosevelt  were  therefore  in  the  main  aimed  at  the  chief  executive,  even 
though  in  disguised  form. 

Viewing  this  problem  from  a  different  angle,  we  can  state  that  a  chief 
executive  should  be  able  to  secure  the  personnel  resources  that  he  needs 
to  attain  his  objectives.  He  may  be  faced,  as  was  the  first  Labor  government 
in  Great  Britain,  with  a  civil  service  which  on  the  whole  is  psychologically 
conditioned  By  sympathies  at  variance  with  his  own.  In  such  an  instance, 
a  speedy  remedy  may  be  repugnant  to  a  merit  and  career  system.18  For- 
tunately, American  administration  has  its  roots  in  all  strata  of  society,  and 
in  the  wake  of  the  New  Deal  it  shows  a  beneficial  mixture  of  attitudes. 

A  career  service  is  the  best  insurance  of  good  administration.  Such  a 
service  is  predicated  on  recruiting  young  men  and  women  with  capacity 

18  The  possibility  of  conflict  between  a  chief  executive's  personnel  needs  and  a  solidified 
career  service  is  obvious.  Periods  of  rapid  social  change  place  the  greatest  stress  on*  a  career 
service.  It  is  also  obvious  that  demands  for  adjustment  can  be  used  as  a  subterfuge  by 
those  interested  in  patronage  and  the  destruction  of  efficient  administration.  Ideally,  a 
career  service  should  be  distinguished  by  a  true  career  ideology,  assuring  whole-hearted  sup- 
port of  administrative  competence  to  any  lawful  government.  This  actually  coincides  with 
main  tendencies  of  professional  attitude.  The  question  of  service  ideology  is  also  closely  linked 
to  that  of  the  basic  rights  of  the  civil  servant.  On  this  point,  see  above  Ch.  21,  "Morale  and  Dis- 
cipline,'1 sec.  3,  "The  Modes  of  Discipline." 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  559 

for  learning  and  growth,  training  them  in  order  to  develop  and  utilize  their 
aptitudes,  and  offering  them  opportunity  for  advancement  in  responsibility 
and  remuneration.  The  advantages  are  teamwork  and  continuity  in  ad- 
ministration, and  an  effective  way  of  attracting  the  ablest  candidates  to  the 
public  service.  However,  the  administration  of  a  career  service  depends  on 
a  recognition  of  its  implications.  Among  these,  employment  practices  are 
extremely  important.  A  career  service  requires  positive  efforts  to  induce  the 
most  competent  individuals  to  compete  in  its  examinations.  It  also  requires 
that  examinations  emphasize  capacity  for  growth,  with  achievement  meas- 
ured only  to  the  extent  that  it  also  indicates  ability  and  promise.  Mediocrity 
would  not  be  a  proper  measure  since  it  makes  inevitable  the  need  for  re- 
cruitment at  levels  higher  than  the  present  entrance  grades  to  compensate 
for  inadequacies  in  general  ability.19 

However  competently  a  career  system  is  administered,  an  occasional  in- 
jection of  employees  from  outside  the  service  in  higher-grade  positions  can 
be  justified.  New  techniques  in  technical  and  professional  services  require 
new  employees,  both  on  a  temporary  and  on  a  permanent  basis,  to  provide 
leadership  in  the  use  of  these  techniques.  Also,  the  stimulus  of  competition 
from  outside  an  organization,  if  limited  in  its  application  so  as  to  preserve 
the  career  idea,  is  a  useful  incentive  to  employees  to  keep  abreast  of  devel- 
opments in  their  fields.  Of  course,  any  extensive  need  for  outside  recruit- 
ment at  higher  grades  is  a  reflection  on  the  ability  available  within  an 
organization.  On  the  other  hand,  complete  failure  to  recruit  employees 
occasionally  at  the  higher  grades  is  probably  also  a  reflection  on  the  organi- 
zation, because  it  might  demonstrate  self-complacency. 

Recruitment.  In  general,  public  personnel  agencies  have  done  a  poorer 
job  in  recruitment  than  in  classification.  While  the  classification  techniques 
used  in  the  public  service  are  at  least  as  good  as  those  found  in  private 
;ndustry,  public  recruitment  has  been  inferior  to  that  in  commercial  and  in- 
dustrial enterprise:20  A  notable  exception  occurred  during  World  War  II 
when  the  federal  government— face  to  face  with  a  need  for  more  than  two 
million  additional  employees  while  the  military  services  were  simulta- 
neously withdrawing  more  than  ten  million  individuals  from  the  labor 
force — went  out  to  the  sources  of  manpower  and  used  every  known  device, 
and  some  new  ones,  to  get  help.  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  this 
great  success  was  accomplished  during  a  period  when  competitive  examina- 
tions were  temporarily  abandoned.  Can  the  public  service  in  the  future 

19  The  best  discussion  of  the  need  for  a  career  service  is  provided  in  White,  Leonard 
D.,  Government  Career  Service,  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1935.    C/.  also  above 
Ch.  2,  "The  Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  3,  "Training  for  Public  Administration"; 
Ch.  18,  "The  Tasks  of  Middle  Management,"  sec.  1,  "The  Dual  Function  of  Middle  Manage- 
ment"; and  Ch.  20,  "Administrative  Self-Improvement,"  sec.  1,  "Evolutionary  Currents." 

20  A  good  summary  of  recruiting  practices  in  the  public  service  is  presented  in  Recruiting 
Applicants  for  the  Public  Service,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1942. 


560  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

retain  competitive  examinations  and  yet  meet  the  aggressive  competition 
of  private  industry  and  the  universities  for  talent? 

A  number  of  recruiting  techniques  have  been  devised  to  meet  this  prob- 
lem. Examinations  are  being  coordinated  with  the  school  year  so  that  eligi- 
bility registers  will  be  ready  and  appointments  available  before  graduation. 
Operating  officials  with  university,  professional,  and  commercial  contacts  are 
playing  a  positive  role  in  interesting  competent  individuals  in  government 
employment.  But  more  can  be  done.  Examination  registers  can  be  put  on 
a  continuous  basis  so  that  applicants  for  employment  will  be  able  to  file 
at  any  time  rather  than  during  a  restricted  period.  Advantages  and  oppor- 
tunities in  the  public  service  could  be  better  publicized  through  professional 
associations,  college  personnel  departments,  and  pamphlets.  Finally,  the 
examination  process  can  be  speeded  up  so  that  the  gap  between  the  dates  of 
filing  an  application  and  receiving  an  offer  of  employment  would  be  greatly 
reduced. 

In  other  words,  personnel  agencies  should  not  be  content  with  post- 
office  announcements  or  obscure  "help-wanted"  advertisements  to  stimulate 
competition  for  employment.  The  number  of  applications  received  for  an 
examination  is  never  a  sufficient  guide  to  the  quality  of  recruiting  work 
done;  only  the  quality  of  applicants  indicates  success  in  this  field.  In  the 
same  manner  as  advertising  agencies  test  the  comparative  value  of  various 
media  for  selling  specific  commodities,  public  personnel  agencies  should 
study  the  results  obtained  from  different  recruiting  methods  for  different 
occupations  and  grades  of  positions. 

Examinations.  Traditionally,  the  examining  process  has  occupied  the 
center  of  the  stage  for  civil  service  commissions.21  This  situation  is  his- 
torically explained  since  the  prime  reason  for  their  establishment  has  been 
the  desire  for  improvement  in  selection.  However,  present  trends  show  that 
management  problems  connected  with  classification,  compensation,  place- 
ment, training  and  employee  relations  play  an  increasingly  important  role, 
even  though  examinations  will  probably  always  continue  to  be  of  great 
significance. 

Examining  is  one  phase  of  public  administration  which  borrows  from 
industrial,  educational,  and  military  experience.  Intelligence,  clerical,  and 
trades  testing  programs  are  similar  in  all  these  fields.  But  significant 
differences  are  to  be  noted.  Examination  methods  in  the  civil  service  require 
that  applicants  be  ranked  in  the  order  of  their  ability,  from  the  top  down, 
while  military  and  industrial  personnel  processes  tend  to  emphasize  the 
determination  of  the  applicant's  minimum  ability  to  do  the  job  for  which 
he  is  being  examined.  The  civil  service  examination  generally  has  to  ac- 
complish two  purposes:  first,  to  determine  which  applicants  meet  minimum 

21  For  a  detailed  analysis  of  all  types  of  civil  service  tests  see  Sayre,  Wallace  S.  and 
Mandell,  Milton,  Education  and  the  Civil  Service  in  New  York  CttV»  Bulletin  No.  20,  Wash- 
ington: Office  of  Education,  1938. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  56l 

standards;  and  second,  to  determine  which  applicant  from  among  these 
is  best,  next  best,  and  so  on.  It  is  obvious  that  an  examination  which  is 
used  for  both  purposes  in  common  must  be  much  better  than  one  used  to 
determine^only  ability  to  meet  minimum  standards. 

Moreover,  examinations  in  the  public  service  have  to  be  virtually  appeal- 
proof.  THry  must  be  sufficiently  objective  so  that  they  would  produce  equiv- 
alent results  even  if  different  individuals  of  the  same  professional  compe- 
tence were  to  administer  them.  This  necessity  arises  out  of  the  right  of 
appeal,  even  to  the  courts,  available  to  candidates  who  question  the  fair- 
ness of  the  examination  used.  Therein  lies  both  a  stimulus  and  a  limitation 
for  the  examiner  in  a  central  personnel  agency.  It  means  that  every  method 
he  proposes  to  use  he  must  first  judge  by  the  two  criteria  of  technical  value 
and  objectivity.  Furthermore,  the  examiner  in  the  public  service  is  con- 
cerned with  a  third  factor — the  outer  appearance  of  a  testing  technique 
in  the  sense  that  the  examination,  from  the  viewpoint  of  both  legislative 
requirements  and  public  pressure,  shall  look  practical  in  addition  to  being 
technically  sound. 

In  general,  we  may  hazard  the  opinion  that  the  soundness  of  examining 
methods  for  the  public  service  has  not  been  substantially  reduced  as  a  result 
of  these  three  factors.22  While  some  testing  methods  which  appear  to  be 
sound  cannot  be  used  because  of  the  three  limitations,  others  which  are 
effective  have  been  developed.  The  examining  process  in  government  has 
met  the  basic  standards  of  reliability  and  validity  to  approximately  the  same 
extent  as  the  examination  methods  used  by  private  industry. 

The  basic  types  of  tests  used  in  public  personnel  examinations  are  four: 
written  examination,  oral  examination,  performance  demonstration,  and 
evaluation  of  education  and  experience.  These  tests  are  used  in  varying 
combinations,  depending  on  the  type  of  occupation,  the  grade  level  of  the 
job,  and  the  number  of  applicants  anticipated.  The  general  method  is  to 
give  greater  credit  for  the  written  test,  and  little  or  no  credit  for  experience 
in  the  lower  grades  of  occupations.  This  scheme  is  reversed  in  the  higher 
grades,  where  the  oral  test  is  used  in  examinations  for  occupations  when 
skill  in  dealing  with  people  is  important.  The  performance  test,  which 
requires  the  applicant  to  demonstrate  how  well  he  can  do  the  work,  is  used 
mainly  in  examinations  for  trade,  stenographic,  and  typing  positions. 

The  greatest  handicap  to  the  improvement  of  the  examination  process 
in  government  has  been  the  failure  to  evaluate  examinations  scientifically. 
Inadequate  use  of  scientific  methods,  contrasting  sharply  with  the  extensive 
research  programs  of  the.  military  services  in  World  Wars  I  and  II,  has  kept 
examinations  at  approximately  the  same  stage  of  development  as  they  were 

22  Dr.  Uhrbrock,  one  of  the  leading  testing  experts  in  private  industry,  has  stated:  "The 
federal  service  is  far  ahead  of  private  industry  in  the  use  of  modern  selection  methods." 
Administrative  Management,  p.  17,  Washington:  Graduate  School  of  the  United  States  De- 
partment of  Agriculture,  1938. 


562  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

ten  to  fifteen  years  ago.  While  it  is  recognized  that  the  number  of  variables 
in  many  an  administrative  problem  tends  to  reduce  the  possibility  of 
accurate  measurement,  selection  methods  can  be  studied  with  relative  pre- 
cision. This  is  one  phase  of  administration  which  can  be  made  scientific; 
there  should  be  no  need  for  using  methods  based  so  largely  on  mere  opinion 
as  to  what  is  good  and  appropriate. 

Written  Tests.  The  written  test23  is  most  extensively  used  in  public  per- 
sonnel examinations.  When  well  prepared,  it  is  the  best  selection  method 
for  many  types  of  positions.  When  inadequately  prepared,  it  is  frequently 
criticized  as  "academic,"  irrelevant  to  the  job,  and  measuring  factual  knowl- 
edge only.  Written  tests  can  be  grouped  in  the  following  categories:  (a)  gen- 
eral mental  ability  or  specific  mental  abilities,  such  as  verbal  or  quantitative 
reasoning;  (b)  aptitude  for  a  group  of  occupations,  such  as  mechanical, 
engineering,  or  clerical;  (c)  achievement  in  any  particular  field  as  a  result 
of  either  training  or  experience;  and  (d)  personality  and  interests. 

In  the  main,  achievement  tests  are  most  commonly  used  in  the  public 
service,  with  general  mental  ability  tests  in  second  place.  The  emphasis  on 
achievement  tests  arises  from  the  desire  of  operating  officials  to  select  per- 
sons who  will  be  able  to  assume  their  duties  immediately  with  little  or  no 
training.  The  situation  in  this  respect  is  quite  different  in  the  military  serv- 
ices, where  mental  ability  and  aptitude  are  stressed  and  adequate  training 
is  provided  so  that  the  assigned  duties  can  ultimately  be  satisfactorily 
performed. 

Emphasis  on  achievement  may  seriously  restrict  recruitment  by  eliminat- 
ing from  competition  a  large  number  of  able  beginners.  In  the  federal 
service,  the  examination  for  junior  civil-service  examiner  was  specifically 
designed  to  draw  into  government  outstanding  young  applicants  who 
could  be  trained  and  placed  in  positions  where  their  abilities  would  be  best 
utilized.  This  examination  and  the  related  junior  professional-assistant 
examination  have  been  the  stepping-stone  to  appointment  for  many  promis- 
ing federal  administrative  employees.  The  entire  examination  for  junior 
civil-service  examiner  and  part  of  the  examination  for  junior  professional 
assistant  have  been  a  general  mental-ability  test  which  largely  measures 
potential  capacity  rather  than  specific  achievement. 

Primarily  as  a  result  of  studies  made  by  universities  and  the  military 
services,  aptitude  tests  are  now  available  for  trade  and  clerical  positions, 
and  some  central  personnel  agencies  make  extensive  use  of  them. 

For  several  reasons,  written  tests  for  measuring  personality  and  interests 
have  not  been  used  often  in  the  public  service  despite  the  great  importance 
of  these  factors  in  successful  job  performance.  In  the  first  place,  public 

23  A  forthcoming  volume  of  the  Civil  Service  Assembly  will  offer  the  first  comprehen- 
sive description  of  this  field.  For  a  summary  of  the  material  in  this  volume,  see  Sublette, 
Donald  J.,  "The  Preparation  of  Pencil  and  Paper  Tests,"  pp.  71-87,  Readings,  op.  cit.  above 
in  note  6. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  563 

personnel  agencies  have  done  little  in  determining  the  value  of  such  tests, 
while  the  data  on  their  usefulness  in  industry  still  seem  inconclusive.  Second- 
ly, since  only  a  few  tests  of  this  kind  are  available  and  extensive  preparation 
of  new  types  is  beyond  the  resources  of  most  public  personnel  agencies,  the 
continued  use  of  the  same  tests  might  invite  "coaching"  which  would  elimi- 
nate any  value  the  tests  may  have.  Thirdly,  and  perhaps  most  important, 
we  have  little  evidence  to  indicate  that  bright  candidates,  no  matter  how 
unsuitable  their  personalities,  could  not  "beat"  these  tests  by  giving  responses 
which  would  add  up  to  a  score  quite  at  variance  with  their  actual  personali- 
ties. The  significance  of  the  factor  of  personality  is  so  great,  however,  that 
continued  research  in  both  written  and  other  types  of  tests  is  warranted  in 
order  to  obtain  an  adequate  measure  of  human  behavior. 

Returning  to  the  general  subject,  we  may  note  that  the  controversy 
between  those  advocating  the  essay  type  of  questions  and  those  favoring 
short-answer  objective  questions  is  practically  over.  Except  where  the  num- 
ber of  candidates  is  relatively  small,  central  personnel  agencies  are  in  general 
now  using  objective  questions  in  their  written  tests.  The  advocates  of  the 
essay  question  emphasize  its  apparent  value  in  measuring  written  expres- 
sion and  ability  to  develop  an  argument  or  a  subject.  However,  in  attempt- 
ing thus  to  rate  written  expression,  personnel  agencies  are  faced  with  an 
expensive  technique.  It  is  also  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  get  the  general 
agreement  of  several  raters  on  the  score  to  be  assigned  to  the  response.  Poor 
preparation  of  short-answer  tests  has  resulted  in  the  charge  that  they  meas- 
ure only  factual  knowledge.  Actually,  such  tests  can  measure  judgment, 
reasoning,  and  analytical  ability  much  more  precisely  and  inexpensively 
than  the  essay  test  or  any  other  type  of  test. 

It  is  frequently  stated  that  written  tests  are  not  useful  in  examining  older 
candidates,  since  younger  applicants,  it  is  claimed,  have  an  advantage  on  these 
tests.  It  has  not  yet  been  demonstrated,  however,  that  candidates  in  different 
age  groups  but  with  equal  ability  get  different  scores  on  written  tests.  Where 
the  written  test  attempts  to  measure  extensiveness  of  experience,  as  fre 
quently  happens,  it  discriminates  against  the  younger  rather  than  the  oldei 
candidate.  Only  when  the  written  test  attempts  to  measure  knowledge 
based  on  college  or  high-school  curricula  does  it  favor  the  recent  graduate 
and  it  does  so  quite  appropriately  if  the  examination  is  for  an  entrance  grad< 
in  an  occupation  where  such  schooling  is  the  only  qualification. 

Oral  Tests.  The  oral  test24  is  used  far  beyond  the  point  warranted  b] 
available  data  on  its  value.  Its  frequent  inclusion  in  examinations  seem 
to  rest  on  its  apparent  suitability  for  measuring  personal  characteristics 

24  A  complete  discussion  of  this  subject  may  be  found  in  Oral  Tests  in  Public  Pertonnt 
Selection,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1943.  The  oral  test,  though  intended  to  probe  int 
personality  traits,  must  not  be  confused  with  so-called  suitability  investigations,  which  ca 
easily  deteriorate  into  political  witch-hunting  and  .encroachments  upon  fundamental  right 
Sec  above  Ch.  15,  "Legislative  Control,"  sec.  4,  "Quest  for  Accountability/' 


564  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

not  on  its  actual  effectiveness.  It  traditionally  is  part  of  examinations  for 
higher-grade  positions  and  for  positions  involving  extensive  contacts  with 
the  public. 

The  usual  method  for  conducting  the  oral  test  is  to  have  the  applicants 
interviewed  by  a  rating  board,  which  generally  has  three  to  five  members. 
The  members  of  the  board  ask  the  candidate  questions  about  his  back- 
ground or  general  questions  which  will  indicate  his  ability  in  oral  expres- 
sion. Generally,  however,  the  important  facts  of  human  behavior  are  not 
revealed.  The  candidate  is  in  an  artificial  situation,  and  the  questions  asked 
are  on  the  level  of  a  casual  conversation  rather  than  on  that  of  a  serious 
conference.  The  oral  test,  in  such  a  situation,  merely  measures  the  superficial 
aspects  of  personality,  speech,  appearance,  and  general  mental  ability,  as  con- 
trasted with  the  specific  traits  of  leadership,  tact,  and  forcefulness  required 
in  many  positions. 

The  past  few  years  have  witnessed  the  development  of  a  number  of  new 
techniques  which  may  do  much  to  enhance  the  value  of  the  oral  test.  The 
"stress  interview"  attempts  to  put  the  candidate  "on  the  spot."  He  is  rated 
on  his  reactions  to  the  stress  situations,  which  may  even  attempt  to  duplicate 
actual  work  problems.  The  oral  testing  method  devised  by  former  United 
States  Civil  Service  Commissioner  Samuel  H.  Ordway,  Jr.  and  James  C. 
O'Brien  requires  the  candidate  to  describe  from  his  past  experience  inci- 
dents in  which  he  successfully  coped  with  situations  similar  to  those  that 
might  arise  in  the  position  for  which  he  has  applied. 

The  Adjutant  General's  Office  of  the  War  Department  has  made  two 
improvements  in  oral  testing  methods  in  connection  with  the  officer  selec- 
tion program.  In  the  first  place,  although  a  standard  set  of  questions  for 
the  interview  has  been  developed,  the  method  of  questioning  has  been  kept 
flexible.  Secondly,  the  rating  method  is  undoubtedly  more  reliable  than 
the  rather  elementary  techniques  in  general  use.  One  additional  and  prom- 
ising oral  testing  method,  utilized  by  the  British  Army  and  the  Office  of 
Strategic  Services  during  World  War  II  and  also  tried  out  by  the  United 
States  Civil  Service  Commission,  provides  for  discussion  among  several  can- 
didates of  a  topic  selected  either  by  or  for  them  while  the  rating  board 
observes  but  does  not  participate.  This  type  of  oral  test  seems  to  furnish 
better  evidence  on  leadership  abilities  and  personality  adjustment  than  the 
usual  interview. 

The  improvements  here  cited  offer  hope  that  the  oral  test  may  become 
a  significant  factor  in  civil  service  examinations  on  the  basis  of  statistical  evi- 
dence rather  than  on  mere  opinion.  Since  this  test  lends  itself  to  the  same 
scientific  evaluation  as  does  the  written  test,  intensive  study  may  result  in 
substantial  progress.  The  written-  test  offers  little  hope  of  developing  into 
an  adequate  measure  of  personality.  Perhaps  the  oral  test  will  fulfill  its 
promise. 

Evaluation  of  Education  and  Experience.   The  evaluation  of  education 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  565 

and  experience25  seems  to  offer  important  evidence  on  which  to  base  a  candi- 
date's standing  on  the  examination  register.  It  is  continuously  in  use  for 
this  purpose.  However,  no  one  has  yet  demonstrated  objectively  and  pre- 
cisely that  it  has  much  value  for  selection  when  administered  in  accordance 
with  the  usual  practices  of  civil  service  commissions.  It  involves  the  assump- 
tion that  personnel  technicians  or  occupational  specialists  can  make  a  ra- 
tional decision  that,  for  example,  two  years  of  training  in  electrical  engineer- 
ing plus  four  years  of  experience  as  a  design  engineer  of  power-transmission 
lines  is  worth  87  per  cent  in  a  particular  examination,  while  a  degree  in 
mechanical  engineering  plus  three  years  of  experience  in  operating  a  power- 
generating  plant  of  a  specific  size  is  worth  84  per  cent  in  the  same  exami- 
nation. The  process,  except  in  extreme  cases  of  either  outstanding  or 
sharply  inferior  experience,  offers  only  slight  hope  of  reasonably  accurate 
measurement. 

One  recent  major  advance  in  this  field  has  been  the  trend  toward  empha- 
sizing the  quality  of  experience  offered  by  the  candidate  rather  than  the 
quantity.  As  a  corollary  to  this  improvement,  additional  credit  for  experi- 
ence may  be  denied  beyond  a  measure  set  in  advance.  Finally,  the  United 
States  Civil  Service  Commission,  for  the  three  highest  grades  in  the  federal 
service,  is  using  the  technique  of  thorough  investigation  to  obtain  first-hand 
information  on  the  quality  of  experience  offered  by  applicants.  This 
method,  together  with  improvements  that  are  needed  in  rating  the  evi- 
dence after  it  has  been  obtained,  seems  to  offer  the  greatest  assurance  of  prog- 
ress in  experience  evaluation. 

Related  to  the  problem  of  rating  experience  is  that  of  establishing  mini- 
mum education  and  experience  requirements  for  admission  to  civil  service 
examinations.  In  our  discussion  of  classification,  it  was  suggested  that  one 
of  the  criteria  of  a  good  classification  plan  should  be  the  support  it  gives 
to  the  career  idea;  that  in  each  occupational  series,  entrance  classes  should 
be  provided  which  do  not  require  previous  experience  but  only  the  com- 
pletion of  appropriate  preparation  or  training.  This  is  essential,  since  ex- 
perience requirements  for  the  lowest  grade  would  force  the  best  college 
and  high-school  graduates  into  industry.  Conversely,  if  adequate  written 
tests  were  used,  experience  should  be  permitted  as  a  substitute  for  educa- 
tional requirements  in  order  to  extend  still  further  the  area  of  competition. 

Performance  Tests.  In  trade  and  clerical  positions  particularly,  perform- 
ance tests26  have  been  applied  with  great  success  by  central  personnel  agen- 
cies. The  candidate  is  asked  to  do  a  "sample"  of  the  work  that  the  position 
entails,  and  he  is  rated  on  the  skill  he  shows.  The  typist  actually  types,  the 

25  Despite  the  importance  given  to  this  test  in  many  civil  service  examinations,  it  has  not 
been  studied  with  any  great  care.    For  a  discussion  of  the  subject,  sec  Pockrass,  Jack,  "Rating 
Training  and  Experience  in  Merit  System  Selection,"  pp.  97-108,  Readings,  op.  tit.  above  note  6. 

26  This  subject  is  discussed  in  Cozad,  Lyman  H.,  "The  Use  of  Performance  Tests  by  the 
Los  Angeles  City  Civil  Service  Commission,"  pp.  88-96,  Reading,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  6. 


566  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

stenographer  takes  dictation  and  transcribes  her  notes,  the  electrician  repairs 
a  motor,  and  so  on.  Candidates  like  this  type  of  test.  Furthermore,  the 
results  obtained  indicate,  in  general,  ability  to  perform  the  job  successfully. 
The  performance  test  tends  to  be  the  most  expensive  type,  but  its  great 
value  justifies  its  use  in  many  instances. 

Great  care  is  needed  in  the  preparation  of  the  performance  test  in  order 
to  make  certain  that  the  work  samples  selected  are  representative,  and  not 
atypical,  of  the  actual  duties  of  the  position,  since  the  test  cannot  duplicate 
all  the  duties.  In  addition,  it  is  desirable  to  design  the  test  so  that  objective 
ratings  may  be  given,  because  subjectivity  in  the  rating  process  will  destroy 
the  value  of  even  the  best  examination.  For  example,  the  strength  of  the 
welds  made  in  a  welding  test  can  be  measured  by  a  machine  in  quantitative 
terms;  the  accuracy  of  transcription  of  a  stenographer  can  also  be  rated 
against  an  objective  scale  in  order  to  obtain  reliability  in  the  scoring  process. 

Placement.  In  the  main,  the  function  of  proper  placement  of  employees 
has  been  grossly  neglected.  Great  care  has  been  exercised  in  the  examining 
process  for  original  selection,  and  then  the  values  to  be  derived  have  been 
wasted  in  poor  assignments.  In  addition  to  the  placement  of  a  new  em- 
ployee in  order  to  give  him  an  opportunity  to  use  his  knowledge,  skills,  and 
abilities,  the  placement  process  involves  a  follow-up  throughout  his  working 
career  to  make  certain  that  there  is  maximum  utilization  of  his  capacities. 
Relatively  little  attention  has  been  given  to  initial  placement  after  recruit- 
ment, but  even  less  care  has  been  exercised  thereafter.27 

Civil  service  examinations  are  usually  designed  for  the  purpose  of  filling 
a  group  of  vacancies  rather  than  a  single  position.  The  candidates  certified 
from  the  eligibility  register  for  a  specific  vacancy  are  therefore  ranked  in 
the  order  of  their  general  abilities.  The  agency  making  the  appointment, 
however,  has  to  consider  additional  information  in  reaching  its  decision  as 
to  who,  among  the  candidates  certified  by  the  civil  service  commission, 
would  be  best  in  terms  of  experience,  training,  interests,  and  personality. 
Sometimes  the  considerations  involved  in  passing  over  a  higher-ranking 
candidate  are  hardly  valid,  but  generally  civil  service  examinations  need  to 
be  supplemented  by  additional  inquiry  pertinent  to  the  filling  of  vacancies. 

27  The  field  of  service  or  performance  ratings  has  not  yet  been  fully  treated.  However,  a 
well -administered  service-rating  plan  is  essential  to  proper  placement,  training,  and  supervision. 
It  is  the  device  for  recording  periodically  how  well  each  employee  is  performing  and  what  his 
strong  points  and  his  weak  points  arc.  This  information,  if  properly  prepared,  is  invaluable  for 
placement  and  training  purposes.  As  a  development  in  service  rating,  the  United  States  Civil 
Service  Commission  has  stressed  the  preparation  of  standards  of  performance  so  that  the  service 
ratings  can  be  based  on  written  standards  known  to  both  employee  and  supervisor.  Most  of 
the  discussion  of  performance  ratings  has  been  directed  at  the  design  of  the  rating  form,  while 
experience  indicates  that  the  form  is  of  secondary  importance  to  the  understanding  and  accept- 
ance by  supervisors  of  what  is  involved  in  the  rating  process.  Government  and  industrial 
service  ratings  are  discussed  in  Halscy,  George  D.,  Making  and  Using  Industrial  Service  Ratings, 
New  York:  Harper,  1944.  See  also  above  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec.  4,  "Super- 
vision and  Employee  Initiative.'* 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  567 

Shifts  in  functions  within  organizations  require  transfers  of  personnel 
which  should  be  handled  on  the  basis  of  matching  job  requirements  with 
the  abilities  of  the  employees  affected.  Not  only  experience  and  training  but 
also  interests  and  personal  factors  should  be  considered  in  making  these 
transfers.  The  personality  of  the  supervisor,  the  pace  of  work  in  the  unit, 
and  the  opportunity  for  displaying  initiative  are  all  intangible  elements  of 
a  job;  they  may  make  the  difference  between  good  and  bad  placement. 
The  placement  specialist  should  work  with  operating  officials  and  training 
specialists  in  organizing  a  program  for  transferring  employees  among  va- 
rious units  so  that  the  employees  can  be  prepared  for  more  important  posi- 
tions. Some  intern  programs,  such  as  those  of  the  National  Institute  of 
Public  Affairs  in  Washington,  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  and  the 
United  States  Civil  Service  Commission,  use  this  technique  with  excellent 
results. 

Promotions  can  be  considered  part  of  the  placement  program.  In  many 
government  jurisdictions,  promotions  are  made  as  a  result  of  competitive 
examinations  conducted  by  the  civil  service  commission.  However,  operat- 
ing officials  consider  promotion  by  examination  a  limitation  on  their 
authority.  Employees,  on  the  other  hand,  tend  to  favor  this  device  as  an 
objective  method  for  achieving  advancement.  When  all  the  employees  who 
compete  in  a  promotional  examination  are  working  under  the  direction  of 
the  same  supervisor,  it  is  doubtful  whether  the  examination  is  as  valid  a 
measure  for  selection  as  choice  by  the  supervisor.  When  the  supervisor  who 
is  to  make  the  selection  is  not  personally  acquainted  with  the  work  of  all 
the  employees  to  be  considered,  an  examination  can  be  helpful  for  promotion 
as  well  as  open  competition. 

No  adequate  interdepartmental  transfer  system  exists  in  any  large  juris- 
diction, although  some  agencies  of  the  federal  government  have  developed, 
for  their  own  needs,  methods  for  filling  vacancies  by  transfers  within  the 
organization.  The  cost  of  interdepartmental  systems,  which  require  a  cur- 
rent record  of  the  training,  skills,  performance,  and  abilities  of  all  em- 
ployees, is  apt  to  be  high.  Departmental  systems  usually  provide  for  posting 
notices  of  vacancies  on  bulletin  boards  in  addition  to  maintaining  employee 
records  in  the  personnel  office.  This  practice  can  improve  employee  morale 
and  aid  in  sound  placement  since,  even  in  the  largest  organizations,  some 
employees  always  find  themselves  in  dead-end  jobs  without  direct  oppor- 
tunities for  advancement. 

5.  TRAINING 

Types  of  Training.  Training  is  a  fundamental  problem  and  responsi- 
bility of  management  in  any  organization.28  In  the  Army,  the  Chief  of 

28  A  brief  introduction  to  this  subject  is  to  be  found  in  Employee  Training  in  the  Public 
Service,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1941. 


568  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

Staff  has  a  training  specialist  as  one  of  his  immediate  chief  staff  assistants.  In 
private  industry,  progressive  companies  emphasize  training  far  beyond  its 
recognition  in  all  but  a  few  governmental  units.  In  its  highest  development, 
the  training  staff  devotes  itself  to  two  main  objectives:  (1)  maximizing  com- 
munication of  policies,  program  objectives,  and  group  ideas  through  all  levels 
of  the  organization;  and  (2)  instilling  the  habit  of  training  throughout  the 
managerial  and  supervisory  groups. 

Training  may  be  either  formal  or  informal;  definite  values  and  advan- 
tages are  derived  from  each  type.  Informal  training  goes  on  continuously 
in  every  organization,  but  it  has  to  be  part  of  an  over-all  training  program 
to  be  most  efficient.  This  comprehensive  type  of  training  occurs  in  the  day- 
by-day  relationships  of  employee  and  supervisor,  in  conferences  and  staff 
meetings,  in  employee  newspapers  and  organization  publications,  at  meet- 
ings of  professional  associations,  and  in  the  reading  and  study  that  the 
employee  undertakes  at  his  own  volition  or  at  his  supervisor's  suggestion. 
Because  such  training  is  connected  with  the  regular  tasks  of  the  employee, 
he  can  best  integrate  it  with  his  own  experience  and  thereby  profit  from  it. 
Since  there  is  no  compulsion  connected  with  it,  his  motivation  is  positive. 
Its  influence,  whether  good  or  bad,  is  profound. 

No  formal  type  of  training  can  match  in  importance  that  received  from 
the  supervisor.  His  comments  on  the  employee's  work,  his  suggestions  for 
improvement,  and  his  role  in  informing  the  employee  on  new  developments 
in  the  organization,  are  basic  to  the  employee's  progress  and  happiness  on 
the  job.  It  is  for  this  reason  that  the  training  of  supervisors  in  employee 
relations,  in  the  improvement  of  procedures,  and  in  instructing  employees 
has  undergone  such  a  phenomenal  growth,  especially  during  World  War  II 
under  the  outstanding  leadership  of  the  Training  Within  Industry  Service 
of  the  War  Manpower  Commission. 

Formal  training  can  be  divided  into  the  following  categories:  pre-entry 
training,  which  is  preparation  for  entrance  into  the  public  service;  orienta- 
tion, toward  both  the  organization  and  the  specific  job;  in-service  training,  for 
improvement  on  the  present  job  and  for  preparation  for  advancement  as 
well;  and  post-entry  training,  which  is  generally  related  not  to  the  specific 
needs  of  the  organization  but  to  the  individual's  own  personal  desires  and 
occupational  interests. 

Pre-Entry  Training.  Preparation  for  public  service  is  usually  haphazard. 
Despite  the  great  increase  in  interest  in  government  employment  since  1930, 
very  few  public  employees  have  completed  a  school  course  designed  to  pre- 
pare them  for  their  careers.  This  fact  has  advantages  as  well  as  disadvan- 
tages. Because  today  the  public  service  covers  wide  areas  of  technological, 
economic,  and  social  activities,  it  can  use  employees  no  matter  what  special 
interests  and  training  they  may  have.  The  nonspecialized  type  of  recruit- 
ment, if  it  were  supplemented  by  intensive  and  extensive  training  after  en- 
trance into  the  public  service,  would  furnish  an  adequate  foundation  for 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  569 

efficient  administration.  Unfortunately,  however,  most  employees  hired 
without  special  preparation  for  their  work  have  not  been  given  training  after 
appointment. 

In  several  occupations  and  professions,  government  service  offers  the 
principal  employment  opportunities:  forestry,  education,  public  health,  and 
— since  1930— -social  work.  In  these  fields,  academic  institutions  and  pub-i 
lie  officials  have  worked  and  are  working  closely  together  to  make  cer| 
tain  that  the  training  given  meets  the  needs  of  the  public  service.  The 
greatest  recent  advance  in  organized  university  preparation  has  been  in  the 
broad  field  of  public  administration.  University  after  university  has  fol- 
lowed the  lead — if  not  the  approach — of  Syracuse  in  preparing  special  cur- 
ricula, principally  on  the  graduate  level,  for  administrative  training.  Some 
of  the  outstanding  expressions  of  this  trend  are  the  academic  programs  of 
Harvard,  New  York  University,  Cincinnati,  Wayne,  Chicago,  Northwest- 
ern, Minnesota,  California,  and  Southern  California;  a  great  many  other 
universities  are  undertaking  similar  training.29  Such  training  usually  at- 
tempts to  be  broadly  inclusive,  covering  the  major  areas  of  staff  and  line 
operations  in  government  rather  than  making  the  student  a  specialist  in 
any  one  of  them. 

A  fundamental  conflict  in  philosophy  exists  as  to  which  type  of  training 
for  the  public  service  is  best.  Shall  the  training  specifically  attempt  to  give 
the  student  the  rudiments  of  classification,  examining,  budgeting,  procedure 
analysis,  public  welfare,  housing,  public  health,  streets  and  highways,  and 
so  on?  Or  shall  it  approach  training  for  public  administration  from  the  point 
of  view  of  public  law,  public  finance,  political  institutions,  and  history? 
This  conflict  could  be  expected  because  of  the  variety  of  positions  included 
in  public  administration.  The  staff  member  of  a  municipal  civil  service 
commission  will  probably  benefit  more  from  the  first  type  of  training,  while 
the  general  staff  assistant  to  an  important  executive  can  use  the  second  type 
more  profitably.  Obviously,  there  is  need  for  both  kinds  of  training.  Quan- 
titatively, in  terms  of  immediate  employment  opportunities,  the  first  method 
is  more  tempting.  However,  if  aspirants  are  to  become  our  future  top-line 
officials  rather  than  auxiliary  or  staff  specialists,  the  second  approach  has 
greater  validity. 

Internship  is  probably  the  most  effective  device  for  bridging  the  gap 
between  university  training  and  public  employment.  A  number  of  universi- 
ties use  it  for  their  engineering  students.  It  has  also  become  a  customary 
part  of  graduate  training  in  public  administration.  In  the  federal  service, 
the  National  Institute  of  Public  Affairs  annually  brings  to  Washington  a 
group  of  the  most  promising  recent  college  graduates  who  receive  learner's 

29  This  subject  is  comprehensively  dealt  with  in  Graham,  George  A.,  Education  for  Public 
Administration,  Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1941.  Cf.  also  above  Ch.  2,  "The 
Study  of  Public  Administration,"  sec.  3,  "Training  for  Public  Administration,"  and  Ch.  20, 
"Administrative  Self -Improvement,"  sec.  1,  "Evolutionary  Currents." 


570  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

assignments  in  federal  agencies  which  are  supplemented  by  lectures  and 
attendance  at  local  universities.  This  program  has  infused  outstanding 
talent  into  government,  with  subsequent  acclimatization  to  the  conditions 
and  problems  of  public  administration. 

Orientation.  Orientation  programs  offer  rewards  to  an  organization  far 
beyond  their  cost.  Their  values  are  both  immediate  and  of  long-range 
character.  Orientation  relieves  the  employee  of  the  "stage  fright"  associated 
with  entering  a  new  job,  and  is  a  sign  to  him  that  the  organization  is 
interested  in  both  his  welfare  and  in  helping  him  adjust  to  his  new  sur- 
roundings. An  orientation  course  usually  includes  information  about  the 
administrative  structure  of  the  organization,  its  history,  its  functions,  and 
its  personnel  policies.  Frequently  an  opportunity  is  provided  for  meeting 
some  of  the  top  officials.  In  addition  to  orientation  to  the  total  organization, 
there  is  an  equally  urgent  need  for  orientation  to  the  specific  job  and  the 
unit  in  which  the  employee  will  be  working.  All  too  often,  however,  the 
method  still  is  to  show  the  employee  his  desk  and  tell  him  to  go  to  work. 
Many  agencies,  on  the  other  hand,  furnish  newcomers  with  an  employee 
handbook  describing  the  entire  working  environment. 

Manuals  of  operating  procedures  are  extremely  valuable  in  orientation 
to  the  job.  They  set  forth  the  rules,  regulations,  and  processes  in  which 
the  employee  will  be  engaged.  Employee  participation  in  the  preparation 
of  these  manuals  is  an  excellent  in-service  training  technique;  it  requires  the 
employee  to  evaluate  his  work  methods  and  consider  how  his  activity  fits 
in  with  that  of  others. 

Formal  training  classes  are  an  efficient  orientation  method  when  a  num- 
ber of  employees  have  been  recruited  about  the  same  time.  Orientation  to 
clerical  and  stenographic  employees  can  usually  be  provided  on  this  basis  in 
larger  organizations  because  of  the  number  coming  in  approximately  simul- 
taneously. The  training  specialist  may  work  with  the  placement  officer  in 
scheduling  the  entrance  on  duty  so  that  new  employees  start  as  a  group  and 
thus  make  the  training  program  more  economical. 

In  both  orientation  and  in-service  training,  the  training  specialist  acts 
as  adviser  and  assistant  to  top  executives  and  to  supervisory  officials  who 
have  the  responsibility  for  setting  the  objectives  of  training  programs.  Their 
needs  have  to  be  met.  To  put  it  differently,  training  is  a  management  tool 
in  which  the  trainer  assists  the  supervisor  in  getting  work  done.  Working 
from  this  concept,  then,  the  training  specialist  has  to  know  management's 
problems  as  well  as  training  techniques.  He  is  expected  to  assist  the  super- 
visor in  identifying  the  need  for  training  in  the  organization  as  well  as 
know  what  techniques  would  be  most  efficient  in  achieving  the  desired 
results. 

In-Service  Training.  If  there  were  no  changes  in  techniques  or  functions, 
there  would  be  little  need  for  in-service  training.  But  statutes  and  regu- 
lations are  constantly  changing,  and  new  professional  and  administrative 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  571 

techniques  are  constantly  being  evolved.  Shall  the  architect  use  the  knowl- 
edge he  acquired  when  he  went  to  college  in  1928  to  meet  the  problems  of 
tomorrow?  Will  the  clerical  processing  techniques  of  1930  meet  the  needs 
of  today?  Shall  the  physician  be  left  to  his  own  imagination  in  learning 
about  penicillin  and  other  more  recent  medical  developments  ? 

In-service  training  is  only  a  partial  but  appropriate  answer  to  these 
questions.  Certainly  each  employee  has  a  personal  responsibility  for  keep- 
ing himself  posted  on  developments  in  his  field,  and  his  supervisor  has  the 
responsibility  for  furnishing  leadership  in  this  respect.  But  voluntary  effort 
should  be  supplemented  because  all  employees  need  to  use  the  best  tech- 
niques in  their  work,  and  an  organized  training  plan  for  a  group  of 
employees  is  more  efficient  than  individual  efforts  which  will  duplicate  one 
another.  Furthermore,  the  constantly  broadening  areas  of  each  profession 
make  in-service  training  essential.  The  housing  specialist  is  no  longer  just 
an  architect;  he  is  now,  in  addition,  an  economist,  sociologist,  and  political 
scientist.  The  public  personnel  specialist  is  no  longer  merely  a  psychologist 
but  also  a  specialist  in  administration — much  in  the  same  manner  as  an 
army  officer  in  command  of  ground  troops  has  to  know  about  the  problems 
of  air  and  naval  warfare  and  the  use  of  electronic  and  other  scientific 
devices. 

In  the  United  States,  police  and  fire  departments,  municipal  and  state, 
have  had  the  longest  and  probably  the  best  experience  in  public-service 
training.  These  departments  do  not  operate  on  the  assumption  that  they 
can  send  new  employees  out  on  a  beat  or  to  fight  a  fire  immediately  after 
appointment.  Rather,  they  have  established  training  schools  which  use 
the  classroom  for  intensive  presentation  of  the  knowledge  necessary  to  do 
police  and  fire  work,  followed  by  supervised  practice  in  actual  duties. 
Regular  police  and  fire  officers  serve  as  faculty  members  to  teach  a  formal 
curriculum.  In  addition  to  such  training  immediately  after  appointment, 
refresher  courses  are  usually  provided  to  keep  the  men  alert  to  new  tech- 
nical developments  in  their  work.  The  Federal  Bureau  of  Investigation 
and  state  leagues  of  municipalities  have  supplemented  local  training  pro- 
grams by  instruction  which  is  of  special  help  to  small  police  and  fire  de- 
partments with  little  or  no  instructional  facilities  of  their  own. 

The  professional  associations  which  have  grown  from  the  public  service, 
primarily  centered  around  the  Public  Administration  Clearing  House  in 
Chicago,  have  made  a  significant  contribution  to  training  by  means  of  their 
publications  and  conventions.  Housing,  welfare,  police,  fire,  personnel, 
budget,  and  other  public-service  groups,  organized  in  associations,  have 
helped  to  make  true  professions  of  their  work.  One  of  their  most  signifi- 
cant contributions,  considering  the  tremendous  number  of  units  of  govern- 
ment in  the  United  States,  is  to  bring  to  the  attention  of  all  of  their  members 
any  promising  new  techniques  and  practices. 

The  public  service  continuously  enters  new  functional  fields  and  con- 


572  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

scquently  runs  into  skill  shortages  which  have  to  be  met.  For  example, 
the  great  expansion  of  personnel  functions  in  the  federal  government  during 
the  1930s  and  World  War  II  produced  a  shortage  which  could  not  be  met 
simply  by  recruitment  of  qualified  personnel.  Training  was  a  necessity  in 
this  situation.  Employees  were  recruited  from  general  registers  and  then 
prepared  for  their  work  by  means  of  classroom  training  and  supervised 
work-experience.  The  internship  program  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Author- 
ity in  the  fields  of  personnel  and  public  administration  represented  another 
organized  effort  in  the  same  direction.  Lack  of  previous  experience  in 
price  control  and  rationing  made  it  necessary  for  the  Office  of  Price  Ad- 
ministration during  World  War  II  to  use  training  methods  extensively  to 
meet  its  need  for  qualified  technical  and  administrative  employees. 

In  addition  to  their  participation  in  pre-entry  training,  the  universities 
can  do  a  great  deal  in  the  development  of  in-service  training,  although  this 
frequently  requires  an  adjustment  in  terms  of  evening  courses,  short  insti- 
tutes, or  courses  that  cut  across  the  usual  departmental  offerings.  Despite 
such  special  problems,  the  universities  have  made  a  telling  contribution, 
principally  by  means  of  evening  courses  established  to  meet  specific  training 
goals.  Those  universities  which  are  located  in  centers  of  government  em- 
ployment such  as  New  York,  Washington,  Chicago,  San  Francisco,  and 
Los  Angeles  have  organized  evening  courses  which  are  based  on  close 
analysis  of  the  needs  of  government  employees.  The  entire  curriculum  of 
the  Graduate  School  of  the  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  is,  of 
course,  designed  for  this  purpose.  Short  institutes,  such  as  those  conducted 
by  the  University  of  Southern  California,  which  meet  for  a  few  days  of 
intensive  discussion  of  some  area  of  administration,  constitute  a  training 
device  perhaps  more  acceptable  to  the  older  and  more  advanced  employee 
than  the  usual  evening  classes.  As  a  supplement  to  its  regular  class  program, 
the  Graduate  School  of  the  Department  of  Agriculture  has  offered  several 
series  of  high-grade  lectures  on  particular  subjects  which  have  been  helpful 
in  meeting  training  demands. 

The  size  and  type  of  staff  needed  in  the  central  and  departmental  per- 
sonnel offices  to  make  training  effective  is  dependent  on  the  relative  em- 
phasis between  advice  to  supervisors  as  compared  with  formal  training 
programs.  A  few  training  specialists  of  superior  ability  can  perform  the 
first  function,  even  in  a  large  organization.  A  much  larger  staff  at  various 
grades  would  be  needed  to  perform  the  second  function  extensively.  The 
training  staff's  closest  relationship  within  the  personnel  agency  is  with  the 
employment  and  placement  staff  because  training  is  the  main  source  of 
skilled  employees  where  recruitment  falls  short  of  requisitions.  In  addition, 
the  placement  staff  can  advise  the  training  specialists  on  the  results  achieved 
by  training;  at  the  same  time,  it  can  obtain  information  on  training  com- 
pleted by  employees  to  use  for  placement  purposes. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  573 

Post-Entry  Training.  Post-entry  training,  while  for  the  most  part  not 
directly  related  to  the  work  of  the  employee,  is  definitely  of  help  to  an 
organization.  An  example  would  be  training  in  engineering  for  a  person- 
nel specialist  in  a  public-works  or  highway  department.  Training  in  per- 
sonnel work  or  public  administration  in  this  instance  would  be  considered  in- 
service  training;  yet  training  in  engineering  in  our  example  might  be  as 
valuable  to  the  employee  as  the  more  closely  related  work  in  personnel 
administration.  Hence  the  border  between  in-service  and  post-entry  train- 
ing is  indistinct.  Another  example  of  post-entry  training  is  that  of  an 
employee  in  a  professional  or  administrative  position  but  lacking  educa- 
tional preparation  for  it.  He  might  undertake  college  or  university  training 
to  supplement  his  practical  experience. 

It  is  desirable  that  the  training  staff  assist  employees  who  are  interested 
in  such  training  by  furnishing  both  information  on  courses  available  and 
helpful  suggestions  about  curricula.  Additional  training  completed  by  an 
employee  should  be  recorded  in  his  personnel  file  so  that  consideration  of 
his  transfer  or  promotion  may  include  the  course  work  undertaken.  In 
evaluating  this  training,  the  training  staff  should  work  with  the  placement 
officers  so  that  the  organization's  needs  and  standards  may  receive  appropriate 
emphasis. 

Training  staffs  are  sometimes  accused  of  promoting  training  programs 
as  ends  in  themselves  rather  than  as  a  means  for  better  work  performance 
of  employees  and  better  administration.  This  may  merely  reflect  the  broader 
viewpoints  of  training  specialists  as  to  the  knowledge  and  skills  that  are 
desirable.  Unfortunately,  it  may  also  indicate  that  training  has  not  been 
integrated  with  placement  and  management  objectives.  In  practice,  the 
second  alternative  means  that  in  its  educational  work  the  training  staff  has 
gone  off  on  its  own  path. 

For  a  long  period,  training  staffs  have  been  faced  with  the  difficulty  of 
evaluating  the  results  of  their  work.  Because  the  value  of  training  is  not 
readily  recognized  in  many  organizations,  it  is  important  that  adequate 
techniques  of  appraisal  be  developed.  In  general,  the  method  used  has  been 
to  obtain  the  opinion  of  the  supervisors  of  employees  who  have  participated 
in  training  programs.  It  is  difficult,  of  course,  to  summarize  such  opinions 
into  a  precise  report  which  would  be  convincing  to  management. 

Where  the  quantity  of  daily  work  done  in  an  organizational  unit  can 
be  measured,  the  problem  can  be  reduced,  although  not  completely  elim- 
inated, by  means  of  work  measurement  before  and  after  training.  However, 
where  work-count  techniques  are  not  suitable,  the  apparently  objective 
methods  that  have  so  far  been  used,  such  as  the  reduction  of  turnover  after 
supervisory  training,  are  of  questionable  validity.  What  is  needed  are  new 
criteria  which  wiU  help  measure  the  degree  to  which  the  employees  possess 
competence  and  esprit  de  corps  and  to  which  supervisors  have  absorbed  the 
habit  of  continuous  training  of  their  employees. 


574  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

6.  EMPLOYEE  RELATIONS 

Place  of  the  Union.  Employee  relations30  are  no  longer  an  academic 
topic.  While  most  government  employees  are  not  union  members,  the  num- 
ber of  members  is  sufficient  to  make  unionism  an  important  facet  of  public 
personnel  administration.31  Resort  to  strike  by  government-employee  unions 
is  usually  prohibited  by  their  constitutions,  but  strikes  have  occurred  in 
government. 

Legal  provisions  would  usually  prevent  a  closed  shop  in  government 
agencies.  The  chief  issue  in  union-government  relations  revolves  around 
the  degree  of  recognition  accorded  the  union.  Some  officials  meet  every 
union  request  with  a  cry  that  the  closed  shop  is  not  legal.  The  furthest 
that  union  demands  in  the  public  service  generally  go  is  request  for  recog- 
nition of  the  union  as  the  bargaining  agent  for  the  employees  of  the  ad- 
ministrative unit.  The  relative  lack  of  experience  of  government  officials 
in  union  relations  leads  them  to  reject  this  request  with  the  same  vehemence 
that  was  typical  of  private  industry  twenty  years  ago.  Industry  has  shifted 
its  attention  away  from  union  recognition  for  collective  bargaining,  which 
does  not  necessarily  limit  the  employer  in  his  hiring  freedom  or  require 
the  employee  to  join  a  union  or  continue  his  membership.  Private  manage- 
ment is  concentrating  now  on  the  closed  shop. 

Stress  and  Strain.  The  history  of  labor  relations  in  industry  explains 
why  recognition  of  a  union  of  government  employees  accords  with  the  ob- 
jectives of  officials  who  understand  the  value  of  unions,  and  why  it  is  not 
relished  by  other  officials  who  consciously  or  unconsciously  oppose  unions. 
The  existence  of  more  than  one  union  in  an  organization  permits  the  anti- 
union  official  to  play  off  one  against  the  other,  while  the  official  who  wel- 
comes union  assistance  in  management  is  hampered  by  the  multiple 
structure. 

Antagonism  to  unions  in  the  public  service  derives  from  certain  con- 
ceptions of  government  as  an  employer.  It  is  argued  that  the  importance 
of  governmental  functions  makes  potential  interference  with  these  functions 
a  scrJQUs-tbrcat  tojJis.jw^llbuufi  of^frritizens.  However,  the  effects  of 
strikes  of  utility^  transportation,  ?nH  fr^«M^"ct-ry  workers  in  private  in- 
dtistry  may*T>e)ustJlsJaarmf  ul  to  thcjaublitf"  welfare.32  It  is  furthcrjisscrted 


30  The  best  discussion  of  the  subject  is  to  be  found  in  Employee  Relations  in  the  Public 
Service,  Chicago:  Civil  Service  Assembly,  1942.    Cf.  also  above  Ch.  13,  "Informal  Organiza- 
tional," sec.  3,  "Nonhierarchical  Sources  of  Power";  Ch.  19,  "The  Art  of  Supervision,"  sec  3, 
"Problems  of  Supervision";  and  Ch.  21,  "Morale  and  Discipline." 

31  Adequate  retirement  systems,  reasonable  hours  of  work,  sick  leave  and  annual  leave 
are  all  close  to  the  interest  of  employee  unions  and  should  therefore  be  of  concern  to  the 
personnel  agency.     In  many  instances,  hours  of  work  and  leave  regulations  vary  from  depart- 
ment to  department  without  justification.  It  would  be  desirable  for  the  central  personnel  agency, 
working  with  the  budget  office,  to  take  the  leadership  in  standardizing  these  arrangements,  as 
has  largely  been  done  in  the  federal  government. 

32  This  is  not  to  say  that  strikes  are  desirable  in  the  public  service;  no  government- 
federal,  state,  or  local — considers  strikes  of  its  employees  lawful. 


PERSONNEL  STANDARDS  575 

that  the  authority  of  the  government  official  in  bargaining  with  unions  is 
circmmtribed--byJegid[aiive  re^Ulicments  and  enactments.  Yet  the  limits 
of  administrative  authority  are  known  to  unions  and  are  no  adequate 
justification  for  an  absolute  refusal  of  collective  bargaining. 

Unionism  and  Service  Neutrality.  The  possible  impairment  of  the  civil 
servant's  neutrality  in  political  and  economic  issues  is  sometimes  offered 
as  a  reason  for  rejecting  government  unionism  involving  outside  affiliations. 
Those  directly  participating  in  labor  matters  in  government,  such  as  the 
employees  of  the  National  Labor  Relations  Board,  recognize  the  validity 
of  the  argument  so  far  as  they  are  concerned;  they  abide  by  the  principle 
of  an  independent  union.  But  many  government  employees  are  not  so  close 
to  the  industrial  firing  line. 

In  the  same  manner  as  advocates  of  nonpartisan  municipal  government 
point  out  that  there  is  no  Republican  or  Democratic  method  for  building  a 
bridge,  it  may  be  shown  that  there  is  neither  an  AF  of  L  nor  a  CIO  way 
of  delivering  letters,  sweeping  a  street,  or  inspecting  milk.  We  may  also 
speculate,  considering  the  limited  area  of  union  demands,  on  whether  the 
social  basis  of  the  higher  civil  service  in  Great  Britain,  for  instance,  is  not 
a  greater  barrier  to  actual  administrative  neutrality  than  union  membership 
of  the  rank  and  file  of  employees  who  are  far  removed  from  responsibility 
for  policy  decisions.  Perhaps,  too,  the  mores  resulting  from  day-by-day 
employment  in  government  are  a  stronger  influence  on  employee  behavior 
than  dues  paying  and  periodic  attendance  at  union  meetings.*3 

Value  of  Unions  to  Management.  Thus  far,  the  negative  side  of  the 
union  problem  has  been  stressed.  The  positive  values  of  government- 
employee  unions  should  also  be  identified.  Unions  keep  management 
alert  since  slipshod  administrative  practices  will  be  exposed  quickly.  They 
offer  a  more  efficient  method  for  bringing  some  of  the  ideas  of  employees  to 
the  attention  of  the  head  of  the  agency  than  even  the  best-organized  staff 
meetings.  Finally,  the  participation  of  employees  in  management  planning 
is  desirable  for  any  organization.  Its  benefits  were  clearly  indicated  by 
the  experience  of  the  labor-management  councils  sponsored  by  the  War 
Production  Board  in  private  industry  during  World  War  II.  Democratic 
administration  is  based  on  extensive  and  intensive  employee  participation, 
which  in  a  large  organization  at  least  in  part  means  union  participation; 
autocratic  administration  knows  that  unions  are  anathema  to  its  continued 
existence. 

Both  independent  unions  and  unions  affiliated  with  the  AF  of  L  and 
CIO  are  found  in  the  public  service,  while  in  the  trades  area  government 
workers  arc  frequently  in  the  same  unions  with  their  fellow-craftsmen 
working  in  private  industry.  The  AF  of  L  has  a  union  for  federal  work- 

83  Because  of  their  basic  insecurity,  unions  frequently  fight  for  personnel  practices,  such 
as  emphasis  on  seniority  in  promotion,  which  are  retrogressive.  In  other  words,  management  can 
derive  substantial  benefits  from  recognition  of  unions  but  it  also  will  receive  requests  which 
hinder  good  administration. 


576  PERSONNEL  STANDARDS 

ers— the  American  Federation  of  Government  Employees— and  a  separate 
union  for  local  and  state  government  workers.  The  movement  to  combine 
the  two  comparable  unions  of  the  CIO  has  led  in  1946  to  the  formation  of 
the  United  Public  Workers  of  America.  The  National  Federation  of  Fed- 
eral Employees  is  the  ranking  independent  union  which  was  once  affiliated 
with  the  AF  of  L. 

Grievance  Procedure.  Handling  government  employee  grievances  and 
appeals  can  benefit  from  a  few  sound  rules.  Informal  settlement  is  always 
to  be  sought  first.  The  employee  should  be  expected  to  discuss  the  griev- 
ance with  his  immediate  superior,  after  receiving  a  statement  of  the  issue 
in  writing.  The  expensive  and  time-consuming  appeal  procedure  should 
not  be  used  for  grievances  which  can  be  settled  in  the  direct  relationship 
between  the  employee  and  his  supervisor.  Adherence  to  this  principle  also 
avoids  short-circuiting  the  supervisor  and  thus  creating  management  diffi- 
culties. Beyond  that,  the  head  of  the  agency  needs  an  appeals  board, 
preferably  composed  of  employee,  management,  and  personnel-office  repre- 
sentatives. It  hears  the  appeal  if  discussion  with  the  immediate  supervisor 
and  the  next  higher  superior  has  not  resolved  the  problem.  The  appeals 
board  should  make  its  recommendation  to  the  head  of  the  agency  rather 
than  issue  its  own  decision  since  the  responsibility  for  action  should  remain 
with  the  top  executive.  Speed  is  desirable  at  each  stage  of  the  procedure 
so  that  the  employee  will  not  distrust  its  effectiveness. 

Employee  groups  have  sometimes  recommended  that  appeals  be  sub- 
mitted to  an  impartial  board  established  outside  of  the  agency  in  which 
the  employee  works.  In  the  city  of  Los  Angeles,  for  example,  and  in  the 
federal  service  so  far  as  veterans  are  concerned,  employees  have  the  right 
to  appeal  to  the  civil  service  commission.34  An  outside  appeals  board  has  the 
advantage  of  impartiality,  but  its  existence  results  in  the  formal  disposition 
of  problems  which  might  best  be  handled  closer  to  management.  In  small 
city  or  state  governments,  such  an  appeals  board  may  be  needed  to  ensure 
fair  consideration;  in  the  major  federal  agencies,  this  procedure  may  be 
unwarranted,  especially  when  employees  are  represented  on  the  board. 

The  issues  involved  in  union  relations,  employee  participation  in  the 
formulation  of  policies,  and  the  handling  of  grievances  are  complex  and 
deserve  the  close  attention  of  the  personnel  director  and  an  able  employee- 
relations  staff.  This  staff  may  at  times  assume  that  successful  handling  of 
individual  employee  problems  is  a  satisfactory  substitute  for  leadership  on 
the  more  general  aspects.  However,  there  simply  is  no  alternative  to  advising 
supervisors  and  management  on  proper  employee-relations  policies  that  will 
serve  as  an  adequate  framework  for  skillful  handling  of  employee  problems 
on  the  level  where  they  arise. 

34  As  an  interesting  parallel,  under  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  of  1946  (sec.  11) 
hearing  examiners  may  be  removed  "only  for  good  cause  .  .  .  determined  by  the  Civil  Service 
Commission.  .  .  ."  On  this  act,  sec  above  Ch.  23,  "The  Judicial  Test,"  sec.  2,  "The  Admin- 
istrative Process  and  the  Lawyers." 


CHAPTER 


Fiscal  Accountability 

1.  FUEL  FOR  THE  ENGINES  OF  ADMINISTRATION 

Administrative  Responsibility  and  Fiscal  Accountability.  As  general 
erms,  responsibility  and  accountability  may  appear  to  have  almost  identical 
neanings.  In  the  realm  of  administration  both  terms  imply  a  relationship  of 
;ubordination  to  the  intentions  of  a  higher  principal.  Thus  we  speak  in- 
erchangeably  of  the  municipal  director  of  public  welfare  as  being  respon- 
sible to  the  city  manager,  and  of  the  head  of  the  state  police  as  being 
uxountable  to  the  governor.  However,  under  the  political  principle  of 
'government  of  laws,"  the  relationship  of  subordination  to  the  intentions 
}f  a  higher  principal  is  institutional  rather  than  personal;  circumscribed  by 
.egal  norms  rather  than  by  habits  of  dependence;  sustained  by  free  accept- 
mce  of  its  implications  rather  than  by  the  claims  of  superior  authority. 
Effective  answerability  is  therefore  less  a  response  to  specific  demands  made 
at  will  by  a  higher  principal  than  it  is  the  product  of  awareness  of  a  com- 
non  purpose  embedded  in  the  wider  cooperative  context.  Responsibility 
.s  likely  to  suffer  when  its  formalized  elements  —  its  "sanctions"  —  fail  to 
^ear  closely  on  generally  endorsed  ends. 

This  becomes  especially  evident  when  we  consider  the  evolution  of  those 
mechanisms  by  which  government  officials  are  made  to  answer  for  the  use 
of  public  funds  placed  at  their  disposal  for  the  accomplishment  of  defined 
abjectives  —  accountability  in  its  more  immediate  sense.  The  need  for  such 
accountability  springs  from  the  heart  of  popular  government.1  Legislative 
control  of  public  administration  would  be  only  intermittent  and  intolerably 
clumsy  as  well  if  it  were  confined  to  the  lawmaking  function  proper.  For 
it  is  clear  that  sole  reliance  on  the  lawmaking  function  would  reduce  the 
writing  of  marching  orders  for  the  executive  branch  to  statutory  grants  of 
authority  or  their  repeal.  Allocation  of  the  fuel  supply  for  the  engines  of 
administration  on  a  year-by-year  basis  allows  for  much  greater  efficacy  and 

1  Cf.  also  above  Ch.  15,  "Legislative  Control." 

577 


578  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

flexibility  of  legislative  determination.  This  method  of  control,  combined 
with  adequate  examination  of  the  actual  use  of  the  funds  voted,  is  focused 
on  the  questions  of  the  desirable — and  possible —  volume  of  services  within 
the  framework  of  an  agency's  statutory  mandate,  and  of  priorities  among 
alternatives. 

The  maxim  of  fiscal  accountability  on  the  part  of  government  officials 
has  never  been  seriously  challenged.  Indeed,  it  could  not  be  challenged 
without  a  simultaneous  onslaught  on  democracy  itself.  To  develop  the 
most  appropriate  forms  of  fiscal  accountability  has  proved  to  be  an  entirely 
different  matter.  Here  we  have  be^.n  faced  with  a  dual  dilemma.  In  the 
first  place,  both  the  legislative  and  the  executive  branches  have  found  it 
difficult  to  keep  at  a  safe  distance  from  the  Scylla  of  controls  so  unrefined 
as  to  be  practically  worthless  and  the  Charybdis  of  devices  so  detailed  as 
to  be  destructive  of  broaden  perspective.  And  secondly,  we  have  not  yet 
achieved  the  necessary  synthesis  between  suitably  precise  requirements  and 
unimpaired  pursuit  of  constructive  administrative  goals.  Ironically,  though 
not  surprisingly,  the  highest  sense  of  administrative  responsibility  has  col- 
lided all  too  often  with  formal  stipulations  of  fiscal  accountability.  Con- 
versely, the  more  distrustful  and  exacting  these  stipulations  have  been,  the 
less  have  they  attained  their  aim. 

Notwithstanding  procedural  rigidities  of  fiscal  accountability,  it  is  plain 
that  of  all  the  great  powers  of  government  the  most  elastic  and  the  most 
generally  congenial  is  the  spending  power.  It  is  adaptable  to  the  widest 
variety  of  objectives — to  wage  war,  to  buy  peace,  to  regulate  the  acreage 
of  agricultural  crops,  to  build  highways,  to  stabilize  the  price  of  peanut 
butter.  It  is  susceptible  of  countless  techniques  of  application — by  adding 
to  the  public  payroll,  by  contracts  for  the  services  of  private  enterprise,  by 
grants-in-aid  to  states  and  cities,  by  outright  gifts,  by  conditional  loans.  It 
is  supported  by  the  taxing  and  borrowing  powers  of  the  wealthiest  of 
nations.  It  is  subject  to  no  constitutional  restraints  of  consequence.2  And 
if  there  are  economic  limits  on  its  exercise,  they  have  not  yet  been  measured. 
The  disbursement  of  government  funds  is  one  of  the  great  harmonizers  of 
divergent  interests. 

Multitude  of  Voices.  While  the  American  Constitution  is  explicit  that 
"no  money  shall  be  drawn  from  the  Treasury,  but  in  consequence  of  ap- 
propriations made  by  law,"3  the  practice  of  conflict,  compromise,  and 
cooperation  under  the  separation  of  powers  divides  authority  and  influence 
over  the  disposition  of  funds  among  many  hands.  Congress  receives  finan- 
cial requests  from  the  President.  It  obtains  assistance  on  ideas  and  factual 
information  from  the  various  federal  agencies.  And  it  has  the  benefit  of 
the  over-all  vantage  point  of  the  Budget  Bureau  on  the  expenditure  struc- 

2  Among  the  constitutional  literature,  reference  may  be  made  especially  to  Corwin,  Edward 
S.,  The  Twilight  of  the  Supreme  Court,  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press,  1934. 
8  Art.  I,  sec.  9. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  579 

turc  and  the  Treasury  Department  on  the  revenue  picture.  Without  these 
aids  the  lawmaking  body  would  be  helpless  to  consider  most  appropriation 
bills.  Yet  it  is  free  to  disregard  all  such  advice  in  any  particular  case. 

Moreover,  the  legislature  is  importuned  by  lobbies,  and  must  choose 
what  answer  to  give  to  their  demands.  Its  own  members  exhibit  a  spec- 
troscopic  array  of  opinions.  Congressional  rules  of  procedure  afford  few 
automatically  effective  self-disciplinary  checks  against  divisive  tendencies 
in  fiscal  policy.  Last  but  not  least,  the  scheme  of  congressional  organization 
emphasizes  the  pluralism  of  power.4  Separate  committees  in  the  House  and 
Senate  are  charged  with  jurisdiction  over  taxation,  appropriations,  and 
expenditures  in  the  executive  branch.  Many  other  legislative  committees 
concerned  with  particular  subject-matter  areas  contend  for  a  voice  in  finan- 
cial decisions  affecting  their  clienteles.  Over  these,  in  the  House,  the  Rules 
Committee  and  the  majority  leadership  exercise  a  fitful  control. 

Within  the  administrative  structure  there  is  equal  diversity  of  purpose. 
A  bureau  chief  may  have  plans  for  bettering  his  program  by  the  enlarge- 
ment of  field-service  facilities.  A  field-office  manager  may  come  forth  with 
different  proposals  for  implementing  the  program  in  his  area.  The  depart- 
ment head,  sympathetic  but  harassed  with  alternatives  of  action,  may  fail 
to  grasp  the  implications  completely.  A  cognate  bureau  in  another  de- 
partment may  keep  its  jealous  eyes  on  administrative  rivals  to  its  own 
position.  The  Budget  Bureau  watches  the  scene  with  a  detached  view  of 
operations  and  under  the  institutional  necessity  of  trimming  most  requests 
for  money.  A  Treasury  spokesman  may  reflect  concern  over  the  market 
for  government  securities  if  borrowing  is  to  continue. 

Pressures  and  Restraints.  Purposes  and  pressures  are  dynamic.  Congress 
does  not  exhaust  its  power  in  a  single  exercise,  although  its  action  tends  to 
culminate  in  the  passage  of  legislation.  Administrative  agencies,  on  the 
other  hand,  are  involved  both  before  and  after  legislative  action.  In  con- 
tinuing cycles  they  prepare  and  urge  their  financial  requests  for  the  next 
fiscal  year  while  the  funds  appropriated  for  the  current  fiscal  year  are  being 
spent  and  the  expenditures  of  the  previous  one  are  being  reviewed  and 
analyzed.  Of  course,  objectives  and  methods  of  the  spending  process  alter 
with  time  and  circumstance.  During  the  quarter-century  since  the  passage 
of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921,5  however,  the  mechanisms  for 
formulating  and  implementing  an  integrated  financial  program  for  the 
executive  branch  have  been  steadily  elaborated. 

The  emerging  machinery  has  been  slow  in  taking  form,  tardy  in  re- 
lation to  the  need,  and  feeble  for  the  purpose  at  important  points.  Its 

*This  matter  has  received  renewed  attention  in  the  recent  report  of  the  Joint  Committee 
on  the  Organization  of  Congress,  Senate  Report  No.  1011,  79th  Cong.,  2d  Sess.,  Washington, 
1946,  and  in  the  final  report  of  the  New  York  State  faint  Legislative  Committee  on  Legislative 
Methods,  Practices,  Procedures,  and  Expenditures,  Legislative  Doc.  No.  31,  Albany,  1946. 

M2Stat.20;31U.  S.C.I  1-16. 


580  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

results  still  leave  much  to  be  desired.  The  elements  of  the  system  are  as 
yet  only  partially  understood  and  utilized  by  the  direct  participants  in  the  fis- 
cal process — legislative  and  administrative,  staff  and  line.  Congressional  par- 
ticularism is  often  hostile  to  a  general  approach  that  puts  consistency  and 
the  broader  public  interest  ahead  of  free  barter  over  special  interests.0  On 
the  administrative  side,  bureaus  and  departments  have  their  traditions  of 
autonomy  as  well  as  their  own  program  interests,  and  cultivate  their  sep- 
arate ties  with  legislative  groups. 

Line  establishments  do  not  readily  defer  to  the  restraints  of  coordinating 
bodies.  Staff  agencies  sometimes  need  to  be  reminded  of  the  essential  con- 
ditions of  successful  staff  work.  There  was  a  time,  for  example,  when  a 
budget  director  turned  down  a  request  for  more  funds  from  the  head  of 
the  Antitrust  Division  of  the  Department  of  Justice  with  the  remark  that 
too  many  antitrust  suits  were  bad  for  business.  Yet,  in  spite  of  surviving 
shortcomings,  the  gains  of  recent  years  in  the  techniques  of  fiscal  coordina- 
tion are  impressive  when  contrasted  with  the  splintering  of  responsibility 
that  characterized  nineteenth-century  financial  administration. 

Pattern  of  Legislative  Money  Grants.  Annually  Congress  passes  a  dozen 
or  more  general  appropriation  acts,  each  supplying  funds  for  the  coming  fis- 
cal year  to  one  or  more  of  the  federal  agencies.  Ordinarily  these  acts  are 
voted  during  the  closing  quarter  of  the  expiring  fiscal  year — prior  to  June  30. 
In  addition,  several  deficiency  bills  are  passed  at  irregular  intervals  through- 
out the  year,  disposing  of  the  financial  requests  arising  from  needs  not  antici- 
pated or  acknowledged  when  the  regular  appropriation  bills  were  considered. 
Appropriations  specify  the  purposes  to  be  served  in  all  degrees  of  specificity. 
They  may  be  small  or  large.  A  lump-sum  grant  of  $8  billions  to  the  Works 
Progress  Administration  established  a  peacetime  high-water  mark  for  both 
size  and  generality  in  one  depression  year  of  the  1930's.  In  the  same  year 
the  Indian  Service  of  the  Interior  Department  was  receiving  its  modest 
allowance  in  several  hundred  bits  and  pieces,  each  separately  earmarked 
for  a  particular  locality  or  activity. 

Appropriations  are  grants.  They  are  also  statutory  limitations.  The  ap- 
propriation acts  must  be  passed  in  some  form  each  year  and  are  not  likely 
to  be  vetoed,  whatever  their  final  form.  They  are  therefore  handy  measures 
for  the  attachment  of  riders.  Some  riders  grant  new  authority  to  relieve  past 
inconveniences.  Most  of  them  embody  additional  restrictions,  expressive 
of  current  legislative  sentiment.  Like  barnacles  once  attached,  such  riders 
tend  to  become  in  effect  permanent  parts  of  the  vessel,  being  carried  forward 
from  fiscal  vear  to  fiscal  year. 

Each  government  agency  has  also  its  organic  legislation,  authorizing  its 
existence  and  definme  its  powers.  These  laws  establish  limitations  on  the 
purposes  and  methods  of  expenditures.  Another  group  of  statutes  lays  down 
or  authorizes  uniform  regulations  of  administrative  practice  covering  all 

6  Sec  above  Ch.  15,  "Legislative  Control,"  sec.  1,  "Means  and  Conditions  of  Control." 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  581 

agencies  unless  specifically  exempted — the  salary  limits  of  the  Classification 
Act  of  1923;  government-wide  pay-raise  legislation;  the  retirement  acts;  the 
standardized  travel  regulations;  the  requirements  of  publicity  and  competi- 
tive bidding  on  government  contracts  in  order  to  eliminate  discrimination 
or  recurrent  possibilities  of  scandal. 

A  statute  of  1893  forbids  any  agency  to  hire  any  member  of  the  Pin- 
kerton  Detective  Agency.7  Since  1917  both  the  War  and  Navy  Departments 
have  been  under  an  injunction,  imposed  in  their  appropriation  acts,  not  to 
engage  in  any  time  studies  by  means  of  a  "time-measuring  device" — a 
strange  idea  in  the  day  of  work  simplification  in  administrative  operations. 
A  further  set  of  legislative  restrictions  is  meant  to  protect  congressional 
prerogatives  against  executive  encroachment.  Finally,  the  Walsh-Healey 
Act,8  forbidding  the  letting  of  government  contracts  to  firms  that  do  not 
meet  specified  labor  standards,  is  typical  of  a  category  of  laws  which  limit 
administrative  discretion  in  the  interest  of  promoting  an  ulterior  economic 
policy. 

From  another  point  of  view,  the  character  and  impact  of  these  restrictions 
varies  considerably  with  the  nature  of  the  individual  agency  and  the  imme- 
diate objects  of  its  expenditures.  The  overhead  of  salaries,  office  space, 
supplies,  and  travel  is  common  to  all  agencies  in  some  degree  and  makes  up 
nearly  the  whole  budget  of  regulatory  agencies.  Fiscal  procedures  and  limi- 
tations governing  these  matters  are  widely  standardized  and  minutely 
worked  out.  Different  sets  of  safeguards  are  appropriate  for  payments  of 
interest  on  the  public  debt;  for  loans  to  be  made  to  business  firms;  for  agri- 
cultural-adjustment and  soil-conservation  contracts  with  farmers;  for  veter- 
ans' benefits  and  pensions;  for  the  construction  of  public  works  directly  or  on 
contract;  for  purchases  of  land;  and  for  the  procurement  of  industrial  mate- 
rials and  manufactured  goods.  Superimposed  on  this  class  of  limitations 
are  variations  in  statutory  restrictions  based  on  the  character  of  the  agency 
— civilian  or  military,  temporary  or  permanent — and  on  the  degree  of 
legislative  confidence  in  its  leadership. 

The  administrative  spenders  of  public  funds  must  proceed  in  the  context  of 
all  these  legislative  directives.  It  is  not  necessary  here  to  attempt  a  compre- 
hensive appraisal  of  the  immense  and  detailed  content  of  this  body  of  law. 
Suffice  it  to  say  that  the  whole  edifice  of  fiscal  law  is  an  outgrowth  of 
the  constitutional  separation  of  powers,  and  administrative  agencies  are 
accountable  for  giving  the  law  full  effect. 

Forms  of  Accountability.  It  is  time  now  to  raise  more  specifically  the 
question  of  who  is  accountable  to  whom  and  for  what.  In  formulating  an 
answer,  the  four  focal  points  of  financial  control  should  be  borne  in  mind. 
These  are:  (1)  the  operating  bureau  or  unit  which  actually  spends  the 
money;  (2)  the  larger  agency  of  which  the  unit  is  a  part;  (3)  the  central 

*27Stat.591. 
«49Stat.  2036. 


582  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

offices  through  which  executive  control  is  exercised  and  over-all  staff  or 
auxiliary  services  are  rendered— the  Budget  Bureau  and  the  Treasury;  and 
(4)  the  congressional  committees  dealing  with  revenue  and  expenditure. 

The  major  mechanisms  of  control  must  be  separately  recognized  also.  In 
broad  outline  these  involve:  (1)  the  justification  of  estimates;  (2)  the  su- 
perintendence of  the  use  of  appropriated  funds;  (3)  the  devices  for  timing 
the  rate  of  expenditures;  and  (4)  the  audit  and  settlement  of  accounts. 
Finally,  we  must  take  into  consideration  the  sequence  of  successive  steps  in 
the  processes  of  appropriation  and  expenditure,  which  ordinarily  spread  over 
a  period  of  two  to  three  years — from  the  first  administrative  forethought  to 
the  last  spending  act.  It  is  perhaps  convenient  to  treat  these  factors  by  fol- 
lowing the  various  stages  in  the  life  history  of  appropriations  and  expendi- 
tures as  they  occur  in  order  to  bring  out  the  relevance  of  each  factor. 

In  doing  so,  the  landmark  quality  of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of 
1921  emerges  most  visibly.  In  a  very  real  sense,  the  act  represented  the 
fruition  of  years  of  enlightened  agitation  and  thought.  Although  marred  by 
some  uncomprehending  efforts  and  actions  explainable  only  in  terms  of 
the  immediate  political  situation,  it  charted  a  new  course  in  the  progress 
of  financial  administration.  Looking  back  in  some  respects  to  the  original 
conception  of  Alexander  Hamilton,  it  reversed  the  drift  of  events  during 
an  intervening  century  to  the  fundamental  emphasis  on  the  unifying  and 
consciously  planning  potentialities  of  fiscal  processes  centered  in  the  con- 
stitutional responsibility  of  the  chief  executive.  The  act  created  one  entirely 
new  agency — the  Budget  Bureau,  as  a  staff  arm  of  the  President — and  reor- 
ganized an  existing  group  of  auditing  and  accounting  offices  into  another 
new  establishment,  the  General  Accounting  Office  under  a  Comptroller 
General. 

The  subsequent  development  of  these  two  agencies  has  had  a  profound 
influence  on  the  further  evolution  of  federal  financial  management.  Let  us 
begin  with  the  phase  of  justification  of  agency  estimates  of  expenditures. 
The  full  cycle  begins,  with  the  operating  units  in  the  several  departments 
and  establishments  and  returns  to  them  in  the  end. 

2.  JUSTIFICATION 

Call  for  Estimates.  Each  year  in  June  the  budget  director  issues  a  call  to 
all  federal  agencies  for  their  budget  estimates  covering  the  fiscal  year  to 
commence  thirteen  months  thereafter — July  1.  The  call  for  estimates  is  in 
effect  one  method  of  achieving  accountability.  It  places  responsibility  on 
the  operating  agencies  for  planning,  formulating,  and  reviewing  the  work 
they  see  lying  ahead  of  them,  and  for  presenting  justifications  for  funds 
to  carry  it  on.  The  justifications  must  prove  persuasive  enough  to  induce 
the  President  to  request,  and  Congress  to  approve,  appropriations  that  will 
enable  the  projected  activities  to  go  forward. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  583 

The  call  for  estimates  itself  is  a  substantial  document.9  It  gives  an 
indication  in  general  terms  of  the  President's  program  for  the  future  and 
its  fiscal  implications.  It  requires  all  agencies  to  submit  to  the  Budget 
Bureau  their  estimates— the  so-called  language  sheets,  which  set  out  the 
text  of  what  the  agency  would  like  Congress  to  enact.  It  calls  also  for 
schedules  of  obligations — the  so-called  green  sheets — showing  the  break- 
down of  expenditure,  personnel,  materials,  travel,  printing,  and  the  like. 
It  asks,  finally,  for  justifications  of  the  estimates.  These  consist  of  descrip- 
tions of  the  agency's  organization  and  facilities  and  the  nature  of  its  work 
program,  together  with  supporting  data  indicating  its  financial  needs.  In 
order  to  assist  the  operating  establishments  in  presenting  their  case  with 
care,  the  call  for  estimates  is  accompanied  by  a  series  of  instructions.  The 
usual  deadline  for  the  submission  of  the  materials  requested  is  September 
15.  Only  in  exceptional  circumstances  can  this  deadline  be  extended  without 
jeopardizing  actions  at  a  later  stage  which  have  a  fixed  calendar. 

The  call  for  estimates  is  properly  concerned  with  the  application  of 
objective  criteria  in  the  framing  of  justifications  submitted  by  the  agencies. 
Such  objective  criteria  are  especially  important  as  a  foundation  for  work- 
load forecasts  and  operating  standards  of  general  validity.  Usually,  there- 
fore, the  call  for  estimates  contains  specific  pointers  like  these:10 

Operating  standards  are  essential  for  the  translation  of  workloads  into 
costs.  In  numerous  units  .  .  .  such  standards  and  ratios  have  been  de- 
veloped and  applied  as  effective  tools  of  management  and  as  bases  for 
estimates  of  needed  funds,  personnel,  and  facilities;  e.  g.,  vouchers 
audited  per  examiner;  claims  adjudicated  per  examiner;  cards  tabulated 
per  hour  of  machine  rental;  cards  punched  or  coded  or  sorted  per  oper- 
ator; documents  filed  or  searched  per  file  clerk;  sheets  mimeographed 
per  machine,  per  operator;  lines  typed  per  operator;  man-days  or  crew- 
days  per  acre  or  per  parcel  of  land  surveyed;  cost  per  mile  and  per  hour 
of  vehicle  operation;  ratio  of  employment  office  personnel  to  total  em- 
ployment; ratio  of  payroll  personnel  to  total  personnel;  cubic-foot  costs 
of  new  construction  by  types;  ratio  of  annual  repair  cost  to  total  invest- 
ment; and  for  institutional  activities — cost  per  bed,  cost  per  patient-day, 
personnel-to-patient  ratios,  and  utilization  rates.  As  a  contributory  step 
in  assembling  and  making  more  widely  available  operating  standards 
now  in  use,  and  in  furthering  their  development  and  application,  it  is 
desired  that  to  whatever  extent  such  standards  have  been  developed  each 
justification  text  .  .  .  present  them  in  concise  written  or  tabular  form 
following,  or  as  a  part  of,  the  presentation  of  the  workload. 

Departmental  Consideration.  Receipt  of  the  call  for  estimates  passes  the 
ball  to  the  departmental  budget  officer  whom  each  agency  is  required  by  the 
Budget  and  Accounting  Act  to  designate  as  the  locus  of  its  internal  financial 

9  Cf.  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  "The  Bureau  of  the  Budget:  Its  Evolution  and  Present  Role," 
American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39,  p.  653  ff.,  869  ff.   This  paper  contains  also 
bibliographical  references  to  the  extensive  literature  on  the  budget  process. 

10  Quoted  from  the  call  for  estimates  for  the  fiscal  year  of  1948;  Bureau  of  the  Budget* 
Bulletin  No.  1945-46:24,  sec.  33,  Washington,  June  24,  1946. 


584  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

controls.  The  development  of  budget  offices  proceeded  unevenly  among  the 
federal  agencies  during  the  early  years  of  experience  with  the  act;  the  pres- 
ent situation  still  exhibits  a  wide  range  of  competence  and  imagination. 
The  departmental  budget  officer  in  some  cases  is  little  more  than  a  glorified 
bookkeeper  attached  to  the  office  of  the  agency  head.  In  other  cases,  and 
particularly  where  the  impact  of  World  War  II  was  felt  most  strongly,  the 
budget  officer  has  become  an  important  participant  in  the  management  and 
planning  of  the  department.  For  this  role  he  is  equipped  with  his  own  staff 
to  keep  abreast  of  the  work  of  his  agency. 

Many  variations  from  agency  to  agency  prevail  in  the  internal  proce- 
dures for  assembling  and  reviewing  the  preliminary  estimates  secured  from 
each  of  the  operating  units  within  the  department.  Then  also,  some  antici- 
pated operations  lend  themselves  readily  to  objective  measurement,  while 
others  must  rest  on  little  more  than  informed  forecasts  and  realistic  guesses 
by  those  who  have  been  closest  to  the  particular  program  during*  the  preced- 
ing fiscal  year.  As  we  have  noted,  the  call  for  estimates  makes  explicit  re- 
quest for  objective  data  where  available  or  susceptible  of  development.  Com- 
parative materials  may  also  be  drawn  in,  as  in  the  case  of  field  offices  per- 
forming substantially  similar  functions  for  the  agency  within  limited 
territorial  areas. 

Patently,  it  is  not  enough  for  the  budget  officer  to  add  up  the  sum  of  the 
operating  requests  thus  assembled  and  report  the  total.  Both  before  he 
relays  the  call  for  estimates  to  the  bureaus  and  divisions  and  upon  scrutiniz- 
ing their  requests,  consultation  with  directing  and  planning  top  officials  of 
his  agency  is  needed.  The  several  programs  of  the  department  must  be 
correlated.  Conflicts  over  activity  priorities  among  departmental  subdivi- 
sions must  be  resolved.  Scales  of  values  must  be  established  for  choosing 
among  a  multitude  of  competing  alternatives.  The  estimates  of  staff,  auxili- 
ary and  technical  services — for  such  functions  as  personnel  management, 
travel,  printing,  law  enforcement,  and  public  information — must  be  analyzed 
in  terms  of  their  adequacy  and  necessity  in  relation  to  the  total  scheme  of 
substantive  work  programs  of  the  agency. 

The  terms  of  the  justifications  must  be  reviewed  as  well  as  the  figures 
they  accompany.  Inconsistencies  and  ambiguities  not  only  jeopardize  favor- 
able action  at  higher  levels  but  also  point  up  weaknesses  in  the  agency's 
own  managerial  arrangements.  The  function  of  the  budget  officer  here  is 
that  of  probing  and  questioning — and  drawing  attention  to  issues  that  re- 
quire remedial  action  on  the  operating  or  policy-making  levels.  Except 
within  the  limits  of  already  clearly  expressed  agency  policy,  he  cannot  safely 
attempt  a  resolution  of  the  questions  he  raises  without  first  assuring  himself 
of  the  views  and  attitudes  of  the  agency  head  or  his  deputies. 

The  measure  of  influence  which  this  kind  of  departmental  review  year 
upon  year  exerts  is  a  test  of  the  strength  and  caliber  of  general  departmental 
management.  In  American  administration,  the  tradition  of  bureau  or  divi- 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  585 

sional  autonomy  is  strong.  It  may  be  fortified  by  outside  links — personal 
relationships  between  the  bureau  chief  and  strategically  placed  members 
of  Congress  or  a  tightly  organized  special-interest  clientele.  Such  relation- 
ships may  render  a  particular  bureau's  estimates  well-nigh  untouchable. 

The  first  head  of  the  National  Park  Service  in  the  Interior  Department 
— himself  a  commanding  figure — kept  that  bureau  in  such  a  position.  Occa- 
sionally the  well-dramatized  personality  of  a  bureau  chief,  particularly  one 
connected  with  an  activity  of  such  general  public  interest  as  crime  detection, 
may  have  the  same  effect.  The  budget  officer  single-handedly  cannot  try 
to  change  the  institutional  "facts  of  life."  Lack  of  interest  and  backing  on 
the  part  of  his  agency  head  may  prevent  him  altogether  from  making  a 
significant  contribution  in  his  area.  Nevertheless,  the  trend  of  recent  years 
has  been  to  professionalize  and  invigorate  the  budget  process. 

Pressure  from  the  Budget  Bureau  has  helped.  Moreover,  ordinarily  too 
much  is  at  stake  for  the  future  of  the  agency  to  allow  the  budgetary  aspect 
to  be  slighted.  When  departmental  review  of  internal  estimates  is  under- 
taken actively  and  intelligently,  it  affords  one  of  the  best  occasions  in  the 
entire  range  of  administrative  management  for  program  planning  and 
reappraisal.  This  would  be  inconceivable  without  participation  of  the  agency 
head,  advised  by  his  immediate  staff.  On  him  falls  the  main  burden  of  pub- 
lic responsibility  for  the  success  of  his  department's  total  program. 

Departmental  consideration  of  the  proposed  financial  program  for  the 
next  fiscal  year  also  supplies  opportunity  for  experimentation  with  novel 
methods  of  budgetary  presentation.  Some  types  of  programs  lend  them- 
selves to  analysis  in  project  terms  as  distinguished  from  organizational  units. 
The  Tennessee  Valley  Authority  and  the  Uinted  States  Department  of 
Agriculture  have  made  notable  contributions  to  budgetary  practice  in  this 
direction.  One  good  example — but  not  the  only  one — is  suggested  by  con- 
struction projects  scheduled  over  a  definite  period  of  time;  when  undertaken 
directly  by  the  agency  itself,  these  may  involve  the  activities  of  several 
organizational  units  such  as  engineering,  personnel,  construction,  and 
finance.  Research  projects,  whether  or  not  they  involve  more  than  one  or- 
ganizational unit,  admit  of  definition  in  terms  of  a  stated  goal  and  may  be 
treated  in  the  same  way. 

Review  of  estimates  within  the  agency  may  occur  more  than  once.  At  a 
later  stage,  it  is  not  infrequently  necessary  to  repeat  appraisal  and  reappraisal 
with  a  still  sharper  focus.  The  agency's  estimates  as  initially  submitted  may  be 
returned  by  the  Budget  Bureau  for  reconsideration  and  reduction,  perhaps 
to  a  specified  lower  figure.  Then  the  agency  has  an  opportunity  to  recom- 
mend the  manner  in  which  the  reduction  is  to  be  absorbed.  In  such  a  situa- 
tion, a  high  order  of  critical  analysis  is  required  of  both  the  management 
staff  and  the  program  chiefs,  and  the  claims  to  priority  among  individual 
programs  themselves  must  be  reexamined. 


586  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

Formulation  of  the  Executive  Budget.  Up  to  this  point,  the  process  of 
justification  has  served  to  secure  accountability  for  orderly  planning  and 
correlation  of  the  various  programs  that  each  agency  proposes  to  carry 
forward.  Within  the  Budget  Bureau,  all  departmental  estimates  are  brought 
together  and  examined  in  the  Estimates  Division.11  Its  staff  members  are 
assigned  on  an  agency  basis  so  that  over  a  period  of  years  a  considerable 
degree  of  specialized  knowledge  and  practical  familiarity  with  the  opera- 
tions and  problems  of  each  agency  is  developed  by  individual  budget  exam- 
iners. These  may  in  fact  have  been  informally  consulted  by  the  depart- 
mental budget  officer  while  the  estimates  were  being  prepared  under  his 
guidance.  The  examiners,  in  turn,  may  have  already  called  on  the  resources 
of  the  Budget  Bureau's  Administrative  Management  Division  or  other  staff 
units  to  assist  the  agency  in  solving  some  of  its  recurrent  problems. 

Now  the  process  reaches  the  stage  of  administrative  hearings  under  the 
auspices  of  the  Budget  Bureau.  These  hearings  are  conducted  by  commit- 
tees, each  headed  by  a  senior  staff  member.  The  individual  department  is 
represented  not  only  by  its  top  officials  and  its  budget  officer  but  also  by 
those  of  its  program  chiefs  whose  areas  are  primarily  concerned.  Commit- 
tee hearings  are  informal  but  searching. 

They  may  dwell  on  policy  and  program  questions  as  well  as  operating 
problems  and  cost  standards.  They  may  be  over  in  a  few  hours  for  a  small 
establishment  or  take  weeks  for  a  large  department.  Written  justifications 
are  supplemented  by  oral  discussion.  Particular  attention  is  paid  to  changes 
in  financial  requests  over  those  for  the  current  fiscal  year. 

In  all  these  matters  the  members  of  the  hearing  committees  have  the 
benefit  of  specialized  counsel  from  staff  in  other  divisions  of  the  Budget 
Bureau.  The  Fiscal  Division,  for  instance — occupied  in  the  main  with 
analysis  of  the  broader  governmental  programs  and  their  economic  impli- 
cations— is  in  a  position  to  offer  expert  advice  on  such  subject-matter  fields 
as  social  security,  foreign  commerce,  investment,  transportation,  consumer 
expenditure,  and  federal-state-local  relationships.  The  Statistical  Standards 
Division,  with  its  coordinating  functions  in  the  wide  area  of  data  collection 
as  an  essential  aspect  of  the  administrative  process,  can  contribute  technical 
information  and  professional  judgment  on  agency  plans  involving  fact- 
finding  projects.  The  Legislative  Reference  Division,  as  a  clearance  facility 
for  the  adjustment  of  departmental  intentions  to  the  President's  legislative 
program  and  for  achieving  accord  on  proposed  executive  orders,  is  able  to 
account  for  the  status  of  pending  measures.  The  Administrative  Manage- 
ment Division,  through  its  surveys  and  studies  of  organizational  matters 
and  operating  methods  throughout  the  government,  is  likely  to  possess 
first-hand  knowledge  of  the  conditions  of  agency  management. 

11  For  the  different  phases  of  the  budget  process,  see  Morstein  Marx,  he.  cit.  above  note 
9,  p.  870  tf. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  587 

This  last  division,  though  a  product  of  recent  years,  has  gone  far  toward 
giving  full  expression  to  one  of  the  most  significant  features  of  the  Budget 
and  Accounting  Act — the  integration  of  the  budget  process  with  the  man- 
agerial concerns  of  the  chief  executive.  The  act  expressly  charged  the 
Budget  Bureau  with  the  task  of  studying  problems  of  governmental  struc- 
ture and  operations  in  order  to  promote  "economy  and  efficiency  in  the 
conduct  of  public  service."12  It  is  difficult  to  overestimate  the  importance  of 
this  assignment.  It  gave  a  healthy  emphasis  to  the  positive  core  of  budgeting 
as  a  means  of  developing  a  unified  and  comprehensive  work  plan  for  the 
government. 

Such  a  work  plan  does  not  result  from  a  formalized  adjudication  of 
agency  requests  for  funds.  It  can  take  shape  only  when  there  is  mature 
appreciation  of  the  living  processes  of  administration  as  well  as  firm  grasp 
of  program  interrelations.  Conversely,  the  framing  of  a  work  plan  for  the 
government  as  a  whole  puts  the  spotlight  on  hidden  managerial  weak- 
nesses and  operating  inefficiencies.  These  are  not  eliminated  by  pious  ad- 
monitions alone.  A  workmanlike  approach  is  required  to  show  how  to 
doit. 

The  business  of  the  hearing  committees,  though  removing  the  remain- 
ing doubts  about  facts  or  reasons  through  joint  consideration  of  the  written 
justifications  presented  by  each  agency,  is  merely  preliminary  to  another 
step.  This  is  the  internal  examination  of  the  emerging  picture,  department 
by  department,  by  the  budget  director  assisted  by  an  advisory  review  com- 
mitee  of  annually  changing  membership.  The  outcome  of  this  review 
determines  the  array  of  surviving  issues  and  general  problems  that  can  be 
settled  only  in  conferences  with  the  President. 

The  President's  decisions  give  the  executive  budget  its  final  form.  How- 
ever, the  principle  of  the  executive  budget  means  merely  that  Congress  has 
the  assurance  of  receiving  a  responsible  and  all-embracing  proposal,  framed 
with  an  eye  to  government-wide  rather  than  purely  departmental  interests. 
The  last  word  is  the  legislature's. 

Legislative  Action.  The  executive  budget  is  placed  before  Congress  early 
in  January,  accompanied  by  the  President's  budget  message.  This  message 
contains  the  highlights  of  his  financial  program  for  the  next  fiscal  year, 
including  an  informative  discussion  of  its  anticipated  impact  upon  the 
economy  and  of  the  government's  principal  plans  for  action.  Because 
of  the  increasing  difficulty  of  differentiating  the  contents  of  a  document 
so  fundamental  for  the  welfare  of  the  country  from  the  President's  annual 
message  on  the  State  of  the  Union,  both  messages  have  recently  been  com- 
bined. The  combined  message  also  concerns  itself  with  the  recommenda- 
tions for  the  maintenance  of  economic  stability  and  high-level  employment 

12  Sec.  209  of  the  act. 


588  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

made  annually  by  the  new  Council  of  Economic  Advisers  to  the  President 
under  the  Employment  Act  of  1946.13 

The  federal  government  today  represents  "the  world's  largest  enter- 
prise."14 It  is  therefore  evident  that  its  annual  revenue  program  and  the 
character  of  its  yearly  outlay  have  profound  effects  upon  the  whole  economy. 
Modern  economists  such  as  the  late  John  M.  Keynes,  William  H.  Beveridge, 
and  Alvin  H.  Hansen  have  done  much  to  make  governments  aware  of 
the  opportunities  they  have  at  their  disposal  for  influencing  the  general 
level  of  economic  activities  through  a  carefully  planned  fiscal  policy.15  Fis- 
cal policy  is  made  up  of  four  basic  components — taxation,  borrowing, 
expenditure,  and  debt  management.  Constructive  fiscal  policy,  as  an  in- 
creasingly important  tool  of  public  stewardship,  must  attempt  to  relate 
the  government's  budget  to  the  nation's  budget.  The  latter  is  in  balance 
only  when  the  anticipated  receipts  of  consumers,  business,  and  public  author- 
ities— federal,  state,  and  local — equal  their  projected  expenditures.  These 
expenditures  are  known  as  the  "gross  national  product."16 

Fiscal  policy  can  be  effective  only  when  it  is  bolstered  up  by  more  than 
coherent  revenue  and  expenditure  planning.  It  may  be  contradicted  by 
governmental  wage  policy.  It  may  be  defeated  by  tax  measures  that  impair 
the  formation  and  free  play  of  venture  capital.  It  may  collapse  when  the 
goverment  fails  to  take  prompt  action  in  order  to  prevent  an  inflationary 
spiral  or  an  impending  slump.  In  brief,  it  must  have  the  support  of  other 
public  policies,  including  those  controlling  the  various  types  of  economic 
regulation  and  the  scope  of  spending  operations  such  as  social  security. 
Only  when  fiscal  policy  is  the  reflection  of  a  fully  consistent  working  ap- 
proach permeating  all  activities  of  government  can  it  achieve  its  course- 
setting  ends.  For  this,  a  realistically  considered  budget  is  a  prerequisite. 

Although  the  President's  budget  message  outlines  the  major  considera- 
tions that  underlie  the  proposed  expenditure  structure,  it  has  thus  far  been 
less  revealing  on  the  "background  of  thinking"17  about  the  budget  at  large. 
Nor  is  there  a  routine  technique  for  submitting  to  the  Appropriations  Com- 
mittees on  each  main  point  a  "specific  memorandum  .  .  .  indicating  the 

13  Public  Law  No.  304,  79th  Cong.,  2d  Sess.,  approved  February  20,  1946.    For  a  dis- 
cussion of  the  background  of  this  law,  see  Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  ed.,  "Maintaining  High-Level 
Production  and  Employment:   A  Symposium,"  American  Political  Science  Review,  1945,  Vol.  39, 
p.  1119tf. 

14  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Congress,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  19. 

16  Cf.  Colm,  Gerhard,  "Technical  Requirements,"  in  the  symposium  cited  above  in  note 
13,  p.  1126  ff.\  Wickwar,  W.  Hardy,  "British  Plans,"  ibid.,  p.  1137  #.;  Holcombe,  Arthur  N., 
"Over-all  Financial  Planning  through  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget,"  Public  Administration  Review, 
1941,  Vol.  1,  p.  225  ff. 

M  Cf.  the  President's  Budget  Message  for  the  Fiscal  Year  ending  June  30,  1947,  p.  U, 
Washington,  1946. 

17  Budget  Director  Harold  D.  Smith,  testifying  before  the  Senate  Appropriations  Com- 
mittee, Hearings  on  the  Independent  Offices  Appropriation  Bill  for  1946,  p.  307,  79th  Cong., 
1st  Sess.,  Washington,  1945. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  589 

background  of  particular  proposals."18  The  budget  director  has  pointed 
out  in  congressional  hearings  that  current  practice  leaves  him  little  chance 
of  laying  "our  facts"  before  the  committees.19  This  is  the  more  serious 
since,  in  departure  from  the  theory  of  the  executive  budget,  the  "defense" 
of  the  President's  estimates  before  the  Appropriations  Committees  has  been 
traditionally  entrusted  to  the  representatives  of  the  individual  agencies  con- 
cerned. The  Budget  Bureau  has  no  official  share  in  the  legislative  process, 
except  in  the  role  of  a  watchful  observer  and  an  occasional  source  of  addi- 
tional information  in  response  to  committee  requests. 

Ordinarily  the  Appropriations  Committee  in  either  chamber,  without  any 
penetrating  preliminary  analysis  of  the  executive  budget  as  a  whole,  dis- 
tributes its  various  segments  among  a  group  of  subcommittees,  each  operat- 
ing in  virtual  independence.  The  consequences  of  this  procedure,  with  par- 
ticular reference  to  the  House,  have  recently  been  placed  in  bold  relief 
by  the  report  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Congress:20 

For  instance,  a  bill  appropriating  funds  for  the  Department  of  the  In- 
terior  is  considered  by  the  Interior  Department  subcommittee.  This  sub- 
committee holds  hearings  in  executive  session  from  which  are  excluded 
not  only  the  public  and  the  press  but  all  other  Members  of  Congress, 
even  the  other  35  members  of  the  Appropriations  Committee  who  are 
not  members  of  this  subcommittee.  Members  of  Congress  .  .  .  have  little 
knowledge  of  what  transpires  within  the  subcommittee  until  the  bill  is 
reported.  Opposition  to  the  requested  appropriation  which,  if  informed 
through  open  hearings  and  publicity,  might  give  much  beneficial  infor- 
mation and  suggestions  to  the  subcommittee,  to  the  full  Appropriations 
Committee  and  to  Congress,  is  thereby  stifled  or,  at  best,  put  at  a  de- 
cided disadvantage. 

Moreover,  .  .  .  consideration  of  appropriation  bills  by  the  House 
Committee  on  Appropriations  is  perforce  rather  perfunctory.  The  full 
committee  does  not  consider  it  necessary  to  give  bills  the  same  detailed 
examination  they  have  already  received  in  subcommittee.  Here  also  all 
consideration  is  in  secret  session. 

...  the  usual  procedure  in  the  House  Appropriations  Committee, 
when  a  subcommittee  reports,  is  for  the  subcommittee  chairman  and  the 
ranking  minority  member  to  present  a  brief  summary  of  their  report 
to  the  full  committee.  After  brief  consideration  and  opportunity  for 
amendments,  the  bill  is  then  promptly  reported  to  the  House.  In  prac- 
tice, careful  consideration  of  the  measure  is  thus  limited  to  the  members 
of  the  subcommittee  in  charge,  upon  whose  judgment  the  full  committee 
generally  confidently  relies. 

Reports  of  the  full  committee  on  major  bills  customarily  reach  the 
floor  soon  after  committee  approval.  Under  these  circumstances,  the 
findings  and  printed  hearings  on  appropriation  bills  are  usually  not 
available  for  careful  and  sustained  study  by  the  membership  at  large 
before  the  bills  are  reported  to  the  House  for  its  action.  The  hearings 
are  naturally  massive  in  size  and  complex  in  detail.  As  a  result,  it  is 


20  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  pp.  20-21. 


590  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

not  easy  for  Members  of  the  House  fully  to  inform  themselves  on  the 
complex  contents  of  appropriation  bills  before  they  come  up  for  final 
action  on  the  floor. 

The  virutal  autonomy  of  the  subcommittees  of  the  Appropriations  Com- 
mittee in  either  chamber  and  the  peculiar  safeguards  of  privacy  with  which 
they  have  surrounded  themselves  lead  to  a  destructive  fragmentation  in  the 
legislative  treatment  of  the  executive  budget.  Submitted  to  Congress  as 
the  work  plan  of  the  government,  it  is  analyzed  principally  in  terms  of  the 
needs  of  particular  departments.  In  order  to  overcome  this  distortion  of 
perspective,  Congress  long  ago  consolidated  the  several  appropriation  com- 
mittees in  each  chamber  as  a  much-needed  implementation  of  the  Budget 
and  Accounting  Act.  In  actual  fact,  however,  the  diffusion  of  responsibility 
which  the  consolidation  was  intended  to  remove,  has  come  to  life  again  in 
the  present  scheme  of  subcommittees. 

Fragmentation  of  point  of  view  toward  the  executive  budget  as  a  whole 
encourages  an  alignment  between  individual  subcommittees  on  the  one 
hand  and  their  departmental  clients  as  well  as  outside  pressure  groups  linked 
to  the  departments  on  the  other.  In  addition,  the  degree  of  power  exercised 
by  the  subcommittees  plays  into  the  hands  of  individual  lawmakers  who 
exert  personal  influence  within  their  particular  subcommittees.  This  often 
becomes  conspicuous  at  a  later  stage  when  Senate  and  House  conferees  meet 
in  order  to  iron  out  disagreements  in  their  votes  on  appropriation  bills. 

Congressional  Reform  Proposals.  Equally  consequential  is  the  institu- 
tional separation  between  the  revenue-raising  and  the  appropriating  com- 
mittees. In  the  language  of  the  document  previously  cited,  "Neither,  so  far 
as  congressional  machinery  is  concerned,  gives  any  consideration  to  the  rela- 
tionship between  income  and  expenditures.  The  appropriations  committees 
are  not  required  by  statute  or  rule  to  keep  total  outgo  within  anticipated 
income."21  This  point,  together  with  related  defects  in  the  present  system 
of  fiscal  control,  figures  prominently  in  the  recommendations  advanced  by 
the  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Congress. 

The  committee  "believes  that  Congress  has  not  adequately  equipped  itself 
to  resist  the  pressure  of  departments  and  agencies  in  behalf  of  larger  expen- 
ditures."22 To  provide  better  "equipment"  the  committee  has  recommended 
a  drastic  remedy  —  adoption  each  spring  of  annual  budget  totals  proposed 
by  joint  action  of  the  revenue  and  expenditure  committees.  Once  these  totals 
are  set  by  concurrent  resolution  there  would  remain  two  alternatives:23 

In  the  event,  after  consultation  and  investigation,  that  the  appropria- 
tions committees  are  unable  to  bring  anticipated  expenditures  within 
estimated  receipts,  a  record  vote  expressing  the  policy  of  the  Congress 


,  pp.  19-20. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  591 

to  create  additional  Federal  debt  in  the  amount  of  the  excess  would  be 
required.  The  budget  resolution  would  have  to  be  approved  by  both 
Houses  before  any  appropriation  for  the  next  fiscal  year  would  be  valid. 
Should  total  appropriations  later  be  found  to  have  exceeded  the  total 
budget  figure  as  set  by  the  Congress,  all  appropriations  except  perma- 
nent appropriations  and  those  for  servicing  the  public  debt,  for  veterans' 
pensions  and  benefits  and  trust  expenditures,  would  be  automatically 
reduced  accordingly  by  a  uniform  percentage  designed  to  bring  total 
appropriations  within  the  over-all  limit  previously  fixed. 

The  difficulties  likely  to  arise  from  adoption  of  such  a  proposal  are  not 
obscure.  In  the  first  place,  an  automatic  ceiling  is  a  crude  device  at  best, 
allowing  for  no  differentiation  among  varying  levels  of  priority  with  re- 
spect to  individual  programs  incorporated  into  the  executive  budget.  Past 
experience  with  over-all  ceilings  in  different  governmental  jurisdictions  and 
in  different  substantive  contexts — including  general  tax  and  debt  limitations 
— has  demonstrated  the  irrationalities  of  their  cramping  effects.  Secondly, 
determination  of  annual  totals  after  submission  of  the  executive  budget  to 
the  legislature  raises  a  practical  question  of  appropriate  timing.  Much  of 
the  effort  embodied  in  the  executive  budget  will  come  to  naught  if  it  i$ 
necessarily  unrelated  to  ceiling  figures  adopted  only  after  budget  comple- 
tion. The  internal  balance  of  the  plan  is  in  part  conditioned  on  the  size  of 
outlay*  On  the  other  hand,  it  would  hardly  be  a  feasible  procedure  for 
Congress  to  commit  itself  to  budget  totals  without  having  taken  a  good 
look  at  the  individual  programs  to  be  financed.  Thirdly,  the  self-imposed 
deadlines  on  congressional  action  envisaged  in  the  scheme  can  scarcely  fail 
to  invite  filibuster. 

In  a  sense,  no  doubt,  the  idea  of  budget  ceilings  determined  after  com- 
pletion of  the  government's  annual  work  plan  is  a  partial  negation  of  the 
very  theory  of  the  executive  budget.  The  President  would  ordinarily  have 
reason,  of  course,  to  welcome  a  general  expression  of  sentiment  on  the  part 
of  Congress  before  the  executive  budget  is  formulated.  Yet  there  will  be 
occasions  when  even  in  full  knowledge  of  such  sentiment  he  would  con- 
sider it  his  duty  to  present  facts  and  figures  in  justification  of  higher  expen- 
diture for  vital  programs  on  which  he  would  want  to  argue  his  case.  The 
matter  of  the  best  timing  of  any  legislative  declaration  of  intent,  however 
general  in  form,  would  still  be  perplexing.  A  definite  adoption  by  concur- 
rent resolution  of  budget  ceilings  puts  additional  weight  on  the  time  factor. 

Lastly,  a  uniform  reduction  of  all  appropriations — with  few  exceptions — 
on  a  percentage  basis  destroys  the  opportunity  for  administrative  recon- 
sideration and  adjustment  in  the  volume  and  emphasis  of  individual  pro- 
grams and  activities.  Is  it  realistic  to  assume  that  a  research  enterprise  of 
paramount  importance  for  our  national  defense  could  be  cut  back  in  a 
blindfolded  manner  in  exactly  the  same  way  in  which  an  appropriation 
for  the  construction  of  federal  office-buildings  would  be  reduced  percentage- 
wise? Would  not  the  Secretary  of  the  Navy,  for  instance,  feel  impelled 


592  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

to  press  earnestly  and  vigorously  for  a  reconsideration  of  the  effects  of  such 
over-all  shrinkage  of  funds  on  the  security  of  the  country?  Automatic  re- 
duction is  certainly  no  convenient  avenue  of  escape  from  the  "pressure  of 
departments  and  agencies  in  behalf  of  larger  expenditures." 

Other  committee  recommendations  rest  on  sounder  grounds.  These 
include  suggestions  for  fuller  scrutiny  of  appropriation  bills  by  each  Appro- 
priations Committee  itself;  establishment  of  the  general  rule  of  open  com- 
mittee hearings  and  sessions;  earlier  submission  of  appropriation  hearings 
and  reports  to  the  House  and  Senate;  and  preparation  of  a  uniform  ap- 
propriation classification  to  be  utilized  in  the  hearings.24  Each  suggestion, 
in  the  light  of  current  practice,  is  a  step  in  the  right  direction. 

The  proposals  also  place  desirable  emphasis  upon  expansion  of  compe- 
tent staff  assistance  to  the  appropriation  subcommittees,  and  on  provision  of 
modern  accounting  machinery  and  equipment  for  the  commitee  staffs. 
Inadequate  staffing  of  Congress  is  an  old  and  legitimate  complaint.25  Better 
staffed  Appropriations  Committees  would  at  the  same  time  be  able  to  develop 
working  contacts  with  their  counterparts  in  the  executive  branch,  especially 
the  Budget  Bureau.  The  budget  director  has  spoken  of  such  continuing 
staff  relations  as  "most  profitable."20  By  pooling  the  resources  of  oppo- 
site staff  groups  it  should  be  possible  to  avoid  duplication  of  study  and 
inquiry  for  competitive  reasons.  Cooperative  arrangements  of  this  kind 
might  also  temper  unfavorable  congressional  attitudes  toward  the  budget 
process.  For  instance,  legislators  have  repeatedly  urged  the  Budget  Bureau 
to  assume  the  role  of  a  strong-minded  and  independent  guardian  of  econ- 
omy for  economy's  sake,  while  equally  often  censuring  it  for  reduction  of 
expenditures  proposed  by  agencies  that  happened  to  be  in  the  good  graces 
of  particular  groups  in  Congress. 

The  committee,  finally,  concerned  itself  with  the  reinforcement  of  the 
budgetary  principle  of  integrity  of  appropriations,27  whittled  down  from  its 
theoretical  scope  by  legislative  practices  that  have  grown  up  in  response 
to  need  and  convenience.  It  recommended  that: 

.  .  .  the  practice  of  reappropriating  unexpended  balances  be  discon- 
tinued, except  in  the  case  of  continuing  appropriations  for  public  works, 
and  that  unexpended  balances  revert  to  the  Treasury  as  provided  by  law. 
The  new  amounts  appropriated  each  year  should  indicate  the  total 
money  available  to  each  agency. 

24  ibid.,  pp.  20-21. 

25  Sec  Kogers,  Lindsay,  "The  Staffing  of  Congress,"  Political  Science  Quarterly,  1941,  Vol. 
S6,  p. /I  ff.\  Committee  on  Congress,  American  Political  Science  Association,  The  Reorganization 
of  Congress,  p.  22  ff.t  79,  Washington,  1945.   For  the  evolution  of  the  staffing  practice  of  the 
.louse  Appropriations  Committee,  see  Congressional  Record,  1943,  Vol.  89,  p.  10994  ff. 

28  Loc.  cit.  above  in  note  17,  p.  309. 

27  For  a  discussion  of  the  traditional  principles  of  budgeting  in  their  impact  upon  creative 
iidministrative  management,  see  Smith,  Harold  D.,  "The  Budget  as  an  Instrument  of  Legis- 
lative Control  and  Executive  Management,"  Public  Administration  Review,  1944,  Vol.  4,  p. 
181/7. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  593 

We  also  recommend  that  the  current  practice  of  permitting  transfer 
of  funds  between  appropriation  accounts  and  organization  units  be 
discontinued. 

We  further  recommend  that  a  uniform  system  of  control  be  perfected 
by  the  appropriations  committees  so  as  to  cover  into  the  Treasury  all 
funds  resulting  from  the  sale  of  Government  property  or  services  by  all 
regular  Federal  departments  and  agencies.28 

The  first  of  these  recommendations  is  a  mild  if  debatable  step.  It  would 
merely  exchange  the  inconveniences  of  obscurity  in  the  precise  amounts 
voted  each  year  for  some  added  difficulty  in  ascertaining  the  total  cost  of 
particular  projects  carried  over  several  years,  and  in  estimating  far  in  ad- 
vance just  how  much  may  be  left  of  an  individual  appropriation  June  30. 
The  other  two  proposals  are  more  serious. 

Transfers  of  funds,  if  deliberately  used  to  defeat  a  clear  expression  of 
legislative  purpose,  are  objectionable,  of  course.  But  safeguards  against 
such  abuse  can  be  introduced,  by  requiring  the  Budget  Bureau's  approval 
or  even  current  reporting  of  the  transfers  to  the  Appropriations  Committees, 
without  destroying  the  plain  advantages  of  flexibility  in  the  adaptation  of 
administrative  programs  to  changing  circumstances  which  a  controllable 
authority  to  transfer  funds  affords.  To  prohibit  transfers  altogether  can 
only  lead  to  the  inflation  of  estimates  for  all  accounts  and  units,  so  as  to 
make  sure  that  no  deficiency  will  be  encountered  in  any  of  the  estimates. 

The  covering  of  all  receipts  directly  into  the  Treasury — so  that  they  will 
require  a  fresh  appropriation  by  Congress  before  they  are  available  for 
spending — is  a  salutary  general  principle  where  it  operates  to  control  the 
net  governmental  outlay.  Examples  are  the  miscellaneous  receipts  from 
fees  for  grazing  permits  on  the  public  lands,  the  issuance  of  passports,  court 
costs,  and  the  like.  But  unless  such  a  requirement  were  accompanied  by 
objectionable  permanent  indefinite  appropriations,  it  would  hamstring  the 
prompt  and  efficient  conduct  of  many  business  operations  the  government 
is  engaged  in — the  payment  of  money  orders  or  losses  on  insured  mail  by 
the  Post  Office  Department,  for  instance.  And  if  applied  to  public  enter- 
prises organized  in  corporate  form,  such  as  the  Inland  Waterways  Corpo- 
ration or  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority,  the  requirement  would  go  to 
lengths  rejected  even  by  the  conservative  sponsors  of  the  Government 
Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945. 

3.  BUDGETARY  COORDINATION 

Essence  of  Coordination.  On  the  administrative  side,  the  budget  process 
brings  into  being  a  proposed  work  plan  for  the  government.  Preparation 
of  the  executive  budget  is  therefore  a  demonstration  of  coordinative  proce- 

28  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  23.  Mention  may  be  made  in  this  connection  of  the  search- 
ing analysis  of  the  review  approach  of  the  Appropriations  Committees  by  Macmahon,  Arthur  W., 
"Congressional  Oversight  of  Administration:  The  Power  of  the  Purse,"  Political  Science 
Quarterly,  1943,  Vol.  58,  p.  161  ff.t  380  ff. 


594  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

dure  in  action.  Coordination,  as  we  saw  earlier,29  is  one  of  the  working 
concepts  of  organization — of  all  organization.  Time  and  again  in  previous 
chapters  we  have  identified  manifestations  of  this  fundamental  element  in 
institutional  cooperation.  In  connection  with  our  discussion  of  the  morale 
factor  we  have  noticed  especially  the  democratic  implications  of  effective 
coordination.30  Perhaps  it  is  useful  at  this  point  to  take  a  closer  look  at 
the  coordinative  aspects  of  the  budget  process. 

Much  of  the  literature  on  management  treats  of  coordination  primarily 
as  an  integral  part  of  the  executive  function.  The  coordinative  needs  of 
large-scale  enterprise  are  supposed  to  be  met  in  the  main  in  the  sweep  of 
executive  leadership  and  in  the  anonymous  ministrations  of  higher  staff 
agents.  No  one  would  want  to  minimize  the  contribution  that  wise  top 
direction  buttressed  by  astute  staff  work  is  able  to  make  to  the  sense  of 
unity  so  essential  to  any  organization.  However,  it  is  equally  true  that 
coordinative  action  springing  from  the  center  of  formal  authority  can 
attain  results  only  when  there  is  widespread  receptivity.  Coordination  be- 
comes a  sham  when  it  attempts  to  operate  by  fiat.  One  may  order  men 
to  work  together,  but  the  order  of  itself  does  not  generate  cooperative 
inclinations. 

Moreover,  in  the  organizational  sense  coordination  is  never  consummated 
in  a  single  act.  To  put  it  differently,  it  aspires  to  arrangements  that  will 
endure  as  long  as  they  serve  a  given  purpose.  From  this  vantage  point, 
coordination  is  not  so  much  a  function  as  it  is  a  state  of  working  relation- 
ships. The  test  of  effective  coordination  is  the  pattern  of  relationships 
achieved  rather  than  the  existence  of  coordinative  mechanisms  or  their 
actual  utilization  by  higher  authority.  It  follows  that  coordination  would  be 
futile  if  it  were  confined  to  "laying  down  the  law."  It  must  seek  consensus. 
It  must  convey  reasons.  It  must  elicit  identification  with  its  objectives. 

Stimulation  of  Program  Thinking.  The  "tone"  of  administration  is  in 
part  the  product  of  the  spirit  of  management  that  radiates  from  the  top; 
in  part — and  not  the  smallest  part  by  any  means — the  reflection  of  the  point 
of  view  that  prevails  in  the  operating  cadres  of  the  organization.  Here,  espe- 
cially in  the  crucial  ranges  of  middle  management,31  we  encounter  a  deep- 
seated  tendency  toward  a  microcosmic  outlook.  Capsular  thinking  is  en- 
couraged by  the  institutional  distance  between  the  day-by-day  routine  in 
which  the  operator  is  enmeshed  and  the  loftier  visions  that  present  them- 
selves at  the  apex  of  the  hierarchy.  Even  in  the  highest  intermediate  strata 
of  the  organization — on  the  bureau  and  divisional  levels — attention  is 
usually  concentrated  on  the  particplar  programs  for  which  bureau  and  divi- 

29  See  above  Ch.  7,  "Working  Concepts  of  Organization,"  sec.  3,  "Quest  of  Organizational 
Unity.*' 

80  See  above  Ch.  21,  "Morale  and  Discipline,"  sec.  4,  "Morale  and  Institutional  Pattern." 

81  See  above   Ch.    18,   "The  Tasks  of  Middle  Management,"   sec.  2,   "Supporting  Top 
Direction." 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  595 

sion  chiefs  are  specifically  responsible.82  To  them,  the  total  agency  program 
is  far  less  tangible  and  immediate.  In  fact,  they  may  doubt  at  times  the 
existence  of  such  a  program. 

Although  their  doubts  will  usually  be  without  foundation,  the  self- 
assertive  qualities  of  the  total  program  may  be  obvious  only  to  the  head  of 
the  agency  and  his  entourage.  Policy  pronouncements  will  speak  eloquently 
about  the  comprehensive  program.  Yet  it  is  more  likely  than  not  that  the 
average  line  official  will  scan  each  such  pronouncement  with  only  two  ques- 
tions in  mind:  What  does  it  give  me?  What  does  it  take  from  me? 
Stronger  stimulation  is  required  to  make  the  line  official  aware  of  the  de- 
partment-wide perspective.  And  if  he  does  not  share  in  the  department- 
wide  perspective,  if  he  ignores  it  in  his  limited  area,  how  can  the  entire 
agency  program  ever  be  a  full-bodied  reality?  How  can  he  be  depended 
on  to  fit  his  actions  into  the  broader  framework  of  close-knit  organizational 
interrelations  ?  How  can  he  be  expected  to  serve  as  an  instrument  of  coordi- 
nation? The  budget  process  is  peculiarly  well-suited  to  operate  as  a  correc- 
tive to  such  localized  introversion  and  self-sufficiency. 

Budgetary  justification  of  proposed  expenditures  is  essentially  self -justi- 
fication in  terms  of  the  larger  enterprise.  The  fundamental  point  of  refer- 
ence is  the  need  of  the  whole.  The  password  of  justification  is  the  contribu- 
tion that  each  individual  unit  within  a  particular  agency  is  able  to  make  to 
the  whole  agency  program,  and — on  the  higher  level — each  particular  de- 
partment to  the  whole  governmental  program.  Indeed,  only  through  an 
examination  of  these  specific  contributions  in  their  relation  to  one  another 
is  it  possible  to  spell  out  the  total  program  in  reasonably  definite  terms. 

Coordination  by  Consultation.  A  general  indication  of  the  main  em- 
phases that  are  to  run  through  the  work  program  of  an  agency  for  any 
given  fiscal  year  rarely  derives  directly  from  financial  considerations  alone* 
Such  an  indication  cannot  come  from  the  departmental  budget  officer.  It  calls 
for  leads  from  the  policy-makers  of  the  agency.  Even  these,  however,  have  to 
seek  an  objective  basis  for  the  policy  guidance  they  must  furnish  the  budget 
officer  and  the  line  officials  with  whom  he  has  to  "thrash  things  out."  Before 
the  agency  head  is  in  a  position  to  commit  himself  in  rough  outline  on  the 
kind  of  expenditure  structure  that  would  best  meet  next  year's  needs,  he 
must  weigh  many  factors  in  the  light  of  concrete  data,  confer  with  those 
on  the  second  level  of  command,  take  counsel  with  his  staff  officers — and 
even  check  with  political  associates  outside  his  organization. 

Consultative  procedure  takes  on  a  more  specific  form  as  the  departmental 
budget  officer,  forearmed  by  the  "general  line"  indicated  at  the  top,  starts 
out  on  his  review  meetings  with  the  higher  operating  officials  to  appraise 
the  merits  of  their  estimates.  Ordinarily,  to  the  operating  official  this  is 
merely  the  terminal  phase  of  a  process  of  joint  consideration  that  may  have 

32  See    above    Ch.    9,    "The    Departmental    System,"    sec.    4,    "The    Bureau    Pattern." 


596  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

occupied  a  good  share  of  his  time  during  the  preceding  weeks  as  the  various 
units  in  his  charge,  departmental  and  in  the  field,  argued  their  respective 
fund  requests  before  him.  The  budget  officer's  labor  is  eased  by  the  thor- 
oughness with  which  conflicting  demands  and  activity  maladjustments  have 
been  eliminated  during  the  estimate  planning  within  each  bureau  and  divi- 
sion. From  the  very  moment  that  the  first  field-office  manager  of  the 
Bureau  of  Foreign  and  Domestic  Commerce,  far  up  in  the  Pacific  North- 
west, thoughtfully  scratched  his  chin  and  began  to  ponder  the  prospect  of  the 
coming  fiscal  year,  uncounted  operators  were  prompted  by  the  budget  process 
not  only  to  account  for  themselves  but  also  to  turn  their  eyes  upon  the 
organization  at  large.  It  thus  became  a  matter  of  consequence  to  them  to 
find  out  what  and  how  others  were  doing  in  their  individual  provinces. 

To  this  extent  coordination  by  consultation  is  self-generative.  One  needs 
no  orders  to  achieve  a  modified  arrangement  when  he  discovers  that  he  is 
stumbling  over  the  legs  of  someone  else.  Such  modified  arrangements 
usually  can  be  worked  out  on  the  spot  by  give-and-take  procedure.  In 
other  instances,  when  the  matter  is  more  complex  and  special  assistance 
appears  necessary,  "loose  ends"  may  be  marked  for  a  full-fledged  survey  to 
be  undertaken  by  the  departmental  management  staff.  In  either  case,  the 
foundation  for  curative  action  emerges  in  the  meeting  of  minds  across  juris- 
dictional  boundaries.  The  budget  process  is  a  continuing  incentive  for  every 
one  in  every  corner  to  take  into  account  the  need  for  a  unified  conception 
of  the  entire  organization.  As  this  conception  grows  in  strength,  operators 
are  encouraged  to  develop  an  instinct  for  coordination. 

Departmental  Synthesis.  With  all  the  full-throated  eulogies  of  the  exec- 
utive function  and  all  the  enthusiastic  dissertations  on  the  role  of  central 
staff  offices,  large-scale  enterprise  would  screech  to  an  abrupt  stop  if  suddenly 
deprived  of  the  self-perpetuating  qualities  of  intelligently  steered  line  opera- 
tions. It  is  not  ludicrous  to  think  of  the  departmental  budget  officer  as  a 
monitor  of  efficiency — which  is  in  large  part  coordination.  But  no  one,  not 
even  the  top  executive  of  an  agency,  is  strong  enough  to  swim  against  the 
stream  of  adverse  administrative  attitudes  and  traditions.  Coordination,  too, 
under  auspices  of  the  budget  process  must  face  the  institutional  "facts  of 
life."  It  cannot  maintain  itself  in  its  own  make-believe.  Yet  it  is  capable 
of  turning  into  a  pervasive  influence  and  of  steadily  augmenting  its 
momentum. 

Budgetary  coordination  in  the  departmental  sphere  exerts  its  influence 
not  so  much  because  of  any  sanction  of  superior  authority  but  because  of 
its  capacity  for  "making  sense"  to  those  affected  by  it.  The  sense  it  tries 
to  transmit  to  operating  officials  who  are  fond  of  the  self-contained  life 
must  attempt  to  fasten  upon  their  own  scale  of  values.  That  the  "big  boss" 
wants  it  thus  and  so  will  in  itself  have  little  appeal. 

Where  there  is  confusion  among  objectives  and  conflict  among  programs, 
with  resulting  antagonisms  between  individual  line  chiefs  or  between  them 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  597 

md  the  top  level,  one  cannot  simply  go  in  with  a  whip.  However,  one 
nay  fruitfully  examine  the  deeper  causes;  attain  agreement  on  the  basic 
:acts  controlling  the  situation;  request  from  each  official  involved  his  best 
:hinking  on  a  remedy;  make  each  familiar  with  the  other's  point  of  view; 
work  toward  joint  appraisal  of  all  forthcoming  proposals;  attempt  accept- 
ance of  a  trial  arrangement  to  be  reconsidered  at  a  later  date;  and  cultivate 
the  conviction  that  all  are  likely  to  gain  and  no  one  to  lose  when  irritations 
ire  removed,  working  relationships  placed  above  legitimate  challenge,  and 
operations  geared  to  common  goals.  Departmental  synthesis  is  approxi- 
mated most  closely  when  people  understand  and  appreciate  its  benefits  in 
terms  that  strike  close  to  home. 

Top-Level  Coordination.  The  most  persuasive  argument  for  coordination 
that  is  brought  forth  in  the  budget  process  is  the  argument  from  incon- 
trovertible evidence.  The  departmental  budget  officer  may  have  one  gen- 
eral view  of  coordinative  necessities  and  the  operator  another.  Who  is  to 
tell  abstractly  which  is  right  ?  It  is  quite  a  different  matter  when  the  budget 
officer  is  able  to  say  with  his  sweetest  smile,  "See  here,  Jim,  what  you  want 
to  take  on  is  already  being  done  by  Bob."  Or,  "You  feel  it's  essential  that 
you  go  ahead  with  all  of  these  new  projects;  but  Bill  and  Harry  are  sensible 
enough  to  defer  some  of  theirs,  though  they  feel  exactly  like  you."  Or,  "If 
we  don't  get  more  consistency  and  coherence  into  our  whole  program,  how 
do  you  expect  us  to  get  by  the  Budget  Bureau  and  the  Appropriations 
Committees?" 

This  means,  in  effect,  playing  the  ball  back.  Restraints  are  activated, 
but  the  operator's  judgment  on  the  best  solution  within  the  frame  of  gov- 
erning circumstances  remains  controlling.  And  follow-up,  next  year  at  the 
latest,  is  easy.  Fundamentally  the  same  approach  commends  itself  for  the 
final  review  of  the  entire  body  of  estimates  on  the  part  of  the  Budget  Bureau. 
The  hearing  procedure,  it  is  true,  does  not  allow  opportunity  for  confront- 
ing the  representatives  of  one  department  with  those  of  another.  However, 
the  same  result  is  attained  when  the  bureau's  officials  have  occasion  to  point 
to  lack  of  broader  balance,  contradictions  in  policies,  or  ill-drawn  borderlines 
between  certain  programs  of  one  agency  and  others  undertaken  elsewhere. 

Conferences  between  the  budget  director  or  his  deputy  and  agency  heads, 
individually  or  jointly,  implement  the  hearing  procedure,  within  the  "budget 
season"  or  without.  These  conferences  would  not  carry  far  if  the  budget 
director  were  unable  to  speak  in  the  name  of  the  President,  thus  simultan- 
eously reducing  the  burdens  on  him.  The  legislative  founders  of  the  na- 
tional budget  system  envisaged  close  contact  between  the  President  and  his 
budget  director83 — a  relationship  that  was  strengthened  by  the  Budget 
Bureau's  transfer,  in  1939,  from  the  Treasury  to  the  new  Executive  Office 
of  the  President. 


88  Cf.  Morstein  Marx,  he.  at.  above  in  note  9,  p.  664  ff. 


598  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

Congressional  voices  have  sometimes  been  raised  in  favor  of  a  Budget 
Bureau  that  would  growl  always  and  bite  often.  More  lasting — and  more 
constructive — effects  arise  from  the  less  dramatic  pursuit  of  program  inte- 
gration and  management  improvement  through  counsel  and  recommenda- 
tion. Only  thus  can  a  demoralization  of  departmental  responsibility  be 
avoided.  Only  thus  can  such  responsibility  be  enlisted  positively  for  the  ac- 
knowledgment of  government-wide  ends.  Clearly,  however,  advice  and 
suggestions  from  a  central  staff  agency  must  extend  to  more  than  budgetary 
figures  and  fiscal  mechanisms.  The  Budget  Bureau's  coordinative  task 
calls  for  breadth  of  information,  imaginative  thinking,  competence  in  anal- 
ysis, and  toughness  of  reasoning.  These,  not  formal  authority,  are  the  sales- 
men of  over-all  coordination. 

4.   BUDGET  EXECUTION 

Budget  Principles  and  the  Test  of  Practice.  When  the  appropriation 
acts  have  finally  tjeen  passed  and  become  law,  another  stage  in  the  attain- 
ment of  accountability  in  administration  begins.  This  is  the  expenditure 
process — the  execution  of  the  budget.  As  was  pointed  out  earlier,  appropri- 
ations have  the  twofold  aspect  of  conveying  spending  authorization  as  well 
as  imposing  responsibility. 

Since  for  our  discussion  the  latter  object  is  uppermost  in  mind,  the  first 
inquiry  may  be  directed  to  the  suitability  of  the  budget  as  enacted  for  ac- 
countability purposes.  From  such  a  point  of  view  a  number  of  qualities  are 
desirable  which  in  governmental  practice — municipal,  state,  and  federal — 
are  commonly  realized,  if  only  to  a  certain  degree.  These  qualities  may 
be  summarized  as  budgetary  publicity,  clarity,  comprehensiveness,  unity, 
specification,  prior  authorization,  periodicity,  and  accuracy.34  As  funda- 
mental requirements,  they  seem  obvious  enough.  Yet  none  of  them  has 
been  consistently  satisfied.  Although  emerging  as  matters  of  form,  they 
reflect  among  other  things  how  far  those  framing,  adopting,  and  executing 
the  budget  have  an  adequate  grasp  of  the  total  significance  of  the  process 
in  which  they  are  engaged. 

At  first  glance  it  may  appear  axiomatic  that  funds  ought  not  to  be  made 
available  to  any  government  agency  without  public  notice  of  the  fact.  In 
fascist  countries  prior  to  World  War  II,  the  availability  of  funds  in  amounts 
undisclosed  to  the  public  provided  an  indispensable  means  of  preparation 
for  war.  In  this  country  the  totals  of  wartime  appropriations  and  authori- 
zations were  generally  known,  and  questions  of  secrecy  related  rather  to 
purposes  than  to  sums  voted.  In  time  of  peace  it  is  doubtful  whether  any 
public  purpose  whatever  can  be  so  cogent  as  to  justify  secrecy  about  the 

a4  Cf.  Smith,  he.  cit.  above  in  note  27.  A  broader  treatment  may  be  found  in  Buck, 
A.  E.,  The  Budget  in  Governments  of  Today,  New  York:  Macmillan,  1934.  For  a  compre- 
hensive presentation  of  fiscal  administration  in  the  federal  government,  see  Seiko,  Daniel  T., 
The  Federal  Financial  System,  Washington:  Brookings  Institution,  1940. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  599 

amounts  of  appropriations — even,  for  example,  for  making  atomic  bombs. 

It  seems  equally  axiomatic  that  the  budget  should  be  understandable,  but 
complications  and  ambiguities  are  hard  to  keep  out  of  it.  For  one  thing, 
the  budget  is  likely  to  be  at  the  mercy  of  the  accounting  system  currently 
in  existence.  For  a  long  time  governmental  accounting  in  most  jurisdictions 
has  lagged  far  behind  the  development  of  good  practice  in  some  well- 
managed  private  concerns,  and  inertia  is  a  powerful  force.  Statutory  re- 
quirements of  itemization  in  a  particular  way  are  frequent  obstacles.  It 
takes  not  far  from  a  thousand  quarto  pages  to  present  the  federal  budget 
to  Congress,  including  summary  tables  for  a  quicker  view  in  perspective. 
The  appropriations  are  contained  in  perhaps  a  score  of  separate  acts  inter- 
larded with  much  extraneous  material,  and  there  are  no  underscorings  in 
them  for  the  lay  reader. 

Much  of  this  is  understandable  in  terms  of  the  variety  of  sources  and 
uses  of  public  funds,  and  the  multiplicity  of  agencies  participating  in  the 
spending  process.  More  of  it  can  be  explained  by  the  fact  that  it  would  be 
difficult  to  make  comparisons  if  the  manner  of  presentation  were  changed 
from  one  year  to  the  next.  Reviewing  authorities,  both  administrative  and 
legislative,  over  a  period  of  time  develop  familiarity  with  a  segment  of  the 
budget  and  the  appropriation  language.  They  have  an  understandable 
suspicion  of  innovations  in  the  general  setup.  It  is  harder  to  tell  what 
changes  from  last  year  may  be  hidden  in  a  new  version,  and  direct  com- 
parisons would  be  futile. 

Unless  the  budget  comprehends  all  proposed  expenditures,  its  usefulness 
for  purposes  of  control  and  accountability  is  limited,  and  appraisals  of  its 
over-all  fiscal  effect  must  be  qualified.  Yet  difficult  questions  arise  in  the 
effort  to  achieve  the  ideal  of  comprehensiveness.  One  has  to  do  with  com- 
mercial and  business  activities  of  government.  The  Post  Office  Department, 
for  example,  is  an  enterprise  with  an  annual  turnover  running  to  billions 
of  dollars.  For  many  years  it  showed  a  chronic  deficit  in  operations,  slight  in 
comparison  with  turnover,  for  which  an  appropriation  was  required.  To 
show  in  the  budget  all  anticipated  gross  receipts  and  payments  of  the  Post 
Office  Department  would  inflate  both  federal  income  and  outgo  by  several 
billions  representing  postal  savings  accounts  and  money  orders — money  to 
which  the  government  has  only  technical  title.  To  show  only  the  net  antici- 
pated deficit,  however,  would  give  a  very  partial  impression  of  the  magni- 
tude of  postal  operations. 

The  resolution  of  problems  of  this  sort,  in  conformity  with  the  principles 
of  budget  clarity  and  comprehensiveness,  is  mainly  found  in  the  use  of  an- 
nexed or  subsidiary  budgets,  while  the  main  budget  carries  only  the  net 
deficit  or  surplus.  Another  type  of  difficulty  was  illustrated,  prior  to  World 
War  II,  in  the  experiments  with  double  budgets.  One  provided  for  what 
was  thought  of  as  the  regular  and  continuing  expenses  of  government — 
the  "ordinary  budget" — and  the  other  showed  separately  the  extraordinary 


600  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

expenses  proposed  for  relief  in  a  depression  period  and  later  for  the  defense 
effort. 

In  justification  of  this  dualism,  it  was  urged  that  the  "extraordinary 
budget"  was  intended  to  be  in  the  nature  of  capital  outlays  to  be  amortized 
over  a  period  of  years.  In  the  one  case  the  expected  upward  swing  of  the 
economic  cycle  was  viewed  as  the  period  of  amortization;  and  in  the  other, 
a  postwar  period  of  peace  of  indefinite  length.  In  both  cases,  the  efforts  at 
distinction  proved  rather  impractical  and  were  abandoned  after  trial.85 
Yet  there  is  a  case  for  separating  in  the  budget  matters  of  longer-range  in- 
vestment and  improvement  outlay  from  current  expense,  as  in  the  capital- 
budget  practice  of  New  York  City. 

A  final  and  continuously  troublesome  question  relates  to  the  treatment 
of  permanent  and  indefinite  appropriations.  A  milestone  in  the  efforts  to 
overcome  these  difficulties  was  the  Permanent  Appropriations  Repeal  Act  of 
1934.38  However,  instances  recur  where  particular  receipts  of  the  govern- 
ment are  earmarked  for  special-purpose  spending  in  a  manner  that  defeats 
the  program-coordinating  processes  implicit  in  the  regular  appropriating 
procedure.  An  example  of  this  is  the  appropriation  of  30  per  cent  of  all 
customs  receipts  to  the  Department  of  Agriculture  for  use  in  stimulat- 
ing export  consumption  of  agricultural  commodities. 

Although  the  federal  budget  is  presented  to  Congress  in  one  complete 
annual  document,  supplemental  or  deficiency  estimates  are  often  inescapable. 
While  this  should  not  obscure  the  substantial  degree  of  achievement  of  the 
goal  of  unity  in  the  presentation  of  estimates,  it  is  true  nevertheless — as  has 
already  been  indicated — that  the  appropriations  themselves  do  not  emerge 
as  one  piece.  Current  practice  reflects  strong  traces  of  the  historical  tradi- 
tion that  for  many  decades  put  the  congressional  jurisdiction  over  appropria- 
tions in  the  lap  of  nearly  a  dozen  separate  committees. 

Now  a  single  Appropriations  Committee  in  each  house  has  jurisdiction 
over  all  expenditure  requests,  but  considers  them  in  subcommittees  which 
report  on  them  successively.  Moreover,  the  subcommittees  have  such  a 
measure  of  autonomy  that  in  fact  there  is  never  an  effective  legislative  op- 
portunity for  viewing  the  prospective  or  actual  total  outgo  until  all  the 
appropriation  acts  have  been  passed  and  the  session  is  closed.37  In  the 
execution  of  the  budget,  in  consequence,  there  is  no  over-all  "master  plan" 
to  serve  as  a  point  of  departure  for  governmental  accounting. 

The  degree  to  which  the  budget  and  the  individual  appropriation 
should  specify  sums  and  purposes  is  perhaps  the  most  controversial  question 

85  For  an  example  of  a  more  consistent  practice  of  dual  budgeting,  see  Morstcin  Marx, 
Fritz,  "Germany,"  in  Anderson,  William,  ed.,  Local  Government  in  Europe,  p.  260  ff.t  296  ff., 
New  York:  App'eton,  1939. 

»«48Stat.  1224. 

87  The  annual  "budget  review,"  issued  by  the  Budget  Bureau  upon  the  beginning  of  the 
new  fiscal  year,  gives  the  essential  data,  including  up-to-date  forecasts  revised  in  the  light  of 
later  developments;  but  this,  of  course,  follows  legislative  action. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  601 

of  all.  Presumably,  while  the  estimates  must  present  much  detail,  the  ap- 
propriation acts  ought  to  allow  considerable  flexibility  for  administrativi 
discretion  in  order  to  meet  changes  in  conditions.  As  will  be  demonstrated 
later,88  efforts  to  tie  administrative  hands  by  extremes  of  budgetary  speci- 
fication have  proved  unproductive  and  even  onerous.  The  length  of  tim^ 
from  the  administrative  development  of  estimates  until  expenditures  ant 
actually  made  is  a  virtual  guarantee  that  alterations  in  the  original  planning 
will  be  required.  With  respect  to  new  programs  particularly,  a  delicate 
balance  has  to  be  worked  out  in  executive-congressional  relationships  be- 
tween the  need  for  furnishing  as  much  detail  as  can  fairly  be  foreseen  and 
the  later  reappraisal  if  the  estimates  prove  insufficient  or  wrongly  projected. 

Traditionally  also  there  are  areas  of  national-defense  activity  and  diplo- 
matic and  domestic  intelligence  where  claims  of  secrecy  in  the  use  of  funds 
have  an  important  bearing  on  the  degree  of  specification.  Emergency  ap- 
propriations for  relief  purposes  during  the  depression  of  the  1930's  have 
introduced  another  area  where  lump-sum  appropriations  have  been  justified. 
Here  the  grounds  were  those  of  flexibility  and  urgent  need  for  more  speed 
and  improvisation  than  the  customary  estimating  procedure  accomodates. 
In  addition,  the  relative  equilibrium  of  political  strength  between  Congress 
and  the  chief  executive  has  been  an  important  factor  in  determining  the 
degree  of  specification  imposed  by  the  legislature. 

The  requirement  of  prior  authorization  is  politically  central.  It  can  be 
disregarded  by  the  executive  branch  only  at  its  own  peril.  Still,  a  century 
and  a  half  of  our  history  has  shown  that  occasions  present  themselves  when 
the  risks  have  appeared  to  be  warranted.  Wilmerding  has  brought  together 
many  instances  to  illustrate  that  our  government  has  not  been  slow  to  rec- 
ognize the  ancient  maxim  of  public  safety  being  the  highest  law,  even  when 
acted  upon  by  the  President  on  his  personal  initiative. 

To  take  a  notable  example,  shortly  after  the  outbreak  of  the  Civil  War, 
at  a  time  when  the  allegiance  of  many  federal  officials  was  in  question, 
President  Lincoln  directed  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  to  advance  two 
million  dollars  to  private  individuals  of  known  loyalty  to  pay  for  such  de- 
fense steps  as  might  prove  necessary.  No  disclosure  of  this  move  was  made 
to  the  public  or  to  Congress  for  over  a  year.30  Perhaps  the  closest  approach 
to  a  parallel  in  connection  with  World  War  II  occurred  in  1941  when 
fifty  overaged  destroyers  were  traded  with  Great  Britain  for  sea  and  air 
bases  without  prior  congressional  authorization. 

Discussion  of  the  appropriating  process  has  already  made  explicit  the 
continuous  nature  of  executive  and  congressional  consideration  of  requests 
for  funds.  Nevertheless,  any  methodical  administration  of  expenditures 
must  make  it  possible  from  time  to  time  to  close  the  books  on  successive 

38  See  below  sec.  5,  "Audit." 

89  Cf.  Wilmerding,  Lucius,  Jr.,  The  Spending  Power,  p.  14,  New  Haven:  Yale  University 
Press,  1943. 


602  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

stages  of  operations.  The  rule  that  appropriations  are  made  for  a  single 
fiscal  year  is  generally  observed.  However,  it  is  subject  to  two  classes  of 
exceptions— permanent  continuing  appropriations  and  appropriations  for 
specific  projects  to  be  completed  regardless  of  time. 

The  principal  example  of  the  former  is  the  permanent  indefinite  appro- 
priation for  interest  on  the  public  debt.  This  is  thought  to  be  necessary  to 
give  the  money  markets  adequate  assurance  on  the  public  credit.  Instances 
of  the  latter  are  to  be  found  in  appropriations  for  public  works,  although 
recent  legislative  usage  calls  for  the  appropriation  of  annual  installments 
after  authorization  in  fixed  sums  for  such  projects  has  been  made. 

Mention  should  also  be  made  of  the  common  habit  of  reappropriating 
unexpended  balances — the  exact  amounts  involved  not  being  susceptible  of 
ascertainment  at  the  time  of  reappropriation.  Coupled  with  the  general 
rule  that  appropriations  are  available  for  a  year  or  two  after  the  close  of  the 
fiscal  year  to  cover  obligations  incurred  but  not  paid  for  during  that  year, 
this  practice  serves  again  to  blur  the  definiteness  and  periodicity  of  appro- 
priations. Moreover,  the  general  rule  of  making  appropriations  and  con- 
sidering deficits  and  surpluses  annually  should  not  blind  us  to  the  essentially 
arbitrary  nature  of  using  any  such  fixed  period  of  time. 

Particularly  when  the  budget  is  viewed  more  broadly  as  an  instrument 
of  national  fiscal  policy  to  be  employed  with  conscious  regard  to  its  effects 
on  the  whole  economy,  the  value  of  appraisals  that  would  more  closely  re- 
late to  the  span  of  business  cycles  of  prosperity  and  depression  becomes 
apparent.  Similar  questions  arise  in  the  peacetime  amortization  of  the  pub- 
lic debt  accumulated  in  wartime.  Much  argument  and  speculation  by 
economists  and  students  of  public  finance  has  been  devoted  in  recent  years 
to  attempts  to  work  out  feasible  methods  of  implementing  a  more  expansive 
conception  of  the  budget. 

Divergence  Over  Ultimate  Ends.  The  shortcomings  in  meeting  the 
formal  requirements  of  a  properly  developed  budget  system,  listed  at  the 
outset  of  this  section,  point  up  a  more  basic  lesson  than  that  involved  in 
the  failure  of  individuals  to  understand  the  goals  of  the  system.  There  is 
divergence  over  the  ultimate  ends  to  be  served  as  well.  The  run  of  legis- 
lative responses  to  the  play  of  economic  and  social  forces  is  different,  at 
least  on  particulars,  from  the  executive  response. 

The  aims  of  provincial  pressures  are  apt  to  find  expression  in  legislative 
limitations  on  appropriations.  Lacking  a  reconciliation  of  these  localized 
impulses  at  the  stage  of  formulation  of  the  budget,  the  processes  of  com- 
promise implicit  in  the  final  passage  of  appropriation  acts  and  their  approval 
by  the  President  are  piecemeal  processes.  They  override  formal  require- 
ments. So  also  do  the  institutional  jealousies  that  lead  Congress  to  prefer 
an  atomistic  organization  of  the  executive  branch,  and  to  be  unsympathetic 
to  administrative  mechanisms  for  the  integration  of  policy.  In  the  rudi- 
mentary and  inconsistent  resolution  of  the  conflicting  claims  of  legislative 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  603 

control  and  executive  management,40  the  basis  for  orderly  fiscal  adminis- 
tration is  the  surest  victim. 

Fund  Control.  Responsibility  for  carrying  out  congressional  directives 
in  the  expenditure  process  is  fixed  by  means  of  the  accounting  system.  The 
federal  accounting  machinery  in  the  fiscal  year  of  1945,  for  example,  had 
to  be  geared  to  keep  track  of  no  less  than  332,426,649  government  checks 
paid  by  the  Treasurer  of  the  United  States.41  In  the  maintenance  of  this 
system  the  Treasury,  the  Budget  Bureau,  the  spending  agencies  and  the 
General  Accounting  Office  all  share  in  important  ways — a  fact  that  of  itself 
underlines  the  need  for  effective  correlation. 

Its  first  element  is  fund  control.  This  is  the  treatment  of  each  item  of 
appropriation,  including  many  of  the  appropriation  limitations,  as  a  sepa- 
rate fund  account,  to  be  credited  with  the  amount  of  the  grant  and  charged 
with  the  expenditures  applicable  to  it.  As  to  limitations,  if  the  Department 
of  the  Interior,  for  instance,  is  appropriated  a  sum  with  the  stipulation 
that  no  more  than  a  stated  amount  or  percentage  may  be  expended  within 
the  District  of  Columbia,  the  limitation  can  readily  be  set  up  as  another 
account.  But  if  the  appropriation  is  to  one  of  the  department's  bureaus 
like  the  Geological  Survey,  while  the  limitation  is  applicable  to  the  total 
amount  for  the  department,  control  is  not  so  easy.  Overlapping  provisos  and 
limitations  indefinite  in  amount,  indeed,  make  it  impractical  to  carry  fund 
control  to  its  logical  conclusion. 

Establishment  of  fund  accounts  is  done  on  the  books  of  the  Treasury  for 
all  appropriations,  and  in  each  agency  for  the  appropriations  made  to  it. 
On  requisition  by  these  agencies,  advances  chargeable  to  their  appropriations 
are  made  to  the  chief  disbursing  officer  of  the  Treasury  or  one  of  his  agents. 
The  former  maintains  a  series  of  checking  accounts  with  the  Treasurer  of 
the  United  States.  The  Treasurer  in  turn  acts  as  a  bank  for  payments  and 
deposits.  The  chief  disbursing  officer  and  his  agents  issue  checks  against 
vouchers  properly  certified  by  the  spending  agency  so  long  as  there  is  a 
credit  balance  in  the  applicable  account.  In  this  manner  fund  control  pre- 
vents an  overdrawing  of  appropriations. 

Allotments.  Fund  control  by  itself  is  a  control  of  the  flow  at  the  nozzle. 
It  does  not  prevent  the  creation  of  obligations  that  will  produce  pressures — 
overwhelming  pressures,  as  abundant  experience  testifies — for  deficiency 
appropriations.  To  forestall  these  pressures  and  assure  that  administration 
will  keep  within  the  fiscal  bounds  originally  fixed,  control  is  reinforced  by 
allotments  and  apportionments  as  two  supplementary  devices  of  account- 
ability. A  third  device— centrally  administered  personnel  ceilings—has  lately 
been  introduced  into  federal  management  as  an  additional  control  over  a 

40  Cf.  Smith,  loc.  cit.  above  in  note  27. 

41  Annual  Report  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  for  the  Fiscal  Year  Ended  June  30,  1945, 
p.  124,  Washington,  1946.  This  is  ten  times  the  annual  rate  for  the  years  immediately  prior  to 
1933. 


604  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

troublesome  area.    A  scheme  of  financial  reporting  is  the  mechanism  for 
bringing  about  a  correlation  of  these  devices. 

Within  the  range  of  activities  comprehended  by  a  single  appropriation 
account,  the  agency's  work  program  is  divided  up  in  fiscal  terms  by  means 
of  allotments.  Subdivision  can  be  carried  to  any  desired  degree  of  detail 
and  agency  practice  varies  considerably.  Allotments  are  ordinarily  made 
to  each  of  the  component  organizational  units  of  the  agency,  down  to  a 
given  level.  In  some  circumstances  they  can  also  be  made  for  the  several 
projects  to  be  carried  on  by  such  a  unit,  as  for  categories  of  loans  or  grants- 
in-aid,  for  example.  They  set  the  limits  within  which  the  unit  is  author- 
ized to  proceed  in  drawing  on  appropriated  funds. 

The  importance  of  allotments  differs  in  proportion  to  the  scope  of  ad- 
ministrative discretion  vested  in  the  agency;  it  varies  also  with  the  size  of 
the  sum  in  the  appropriation  account.  Specific  appropriations  leave  less 
room  for  allotments;  lump  sums  are  meaningless  without  them.  For  pur- 
poses of  the  financial  accountability  of  the  agency,  allotments  are  essentially 
a  safeguard  against  the  overobligation  of  appropriations  that  might  occur 
because  a  number  of  hands  are  reaching  into  the  same  pocket  at  once. 

Apportionments.  Apportionments  are  designed  to  prevent  these  hands 
from  reaching  too  deeply  too  soon,  with  the  result  that  all  of  the  year's 
funds  are  gone  before  all  of  the  year's  work  is  done.  In  the  federal  govern- 
ment, the  control  of  apportionments — quarterly  amounts  into  which  the 
annual  appropriation  must  be  divided  in  advance,  and  which  set  limits  to 
the  agency's  spending  during  the  quarter  under  each  appropriation  heading 
— is  vested  in  the  Budget  Bureau.  The  requirement  of  apportionments  was 
orginally  imposed  under  the  antideficiency  legislation  of  1905-1906,42  but 
lapsed  in  innocuous  desuetude  until  the  authority  was  centralized  in  the 
Budget  Bureau  by  Executive  Order  No.  6166  of  June  10, 1933. 

A  classic  example  of  the  evil  the  act  was  designed  to  combat  occurred 
late  in  1879,  when  the  Postmaster  General  asked  Congress  for  an  additional 
sum  of  $2  million  to  supplement  the  appropriation  of  $5,900,000  for  inland 
mail  transportation  on  the  "star  routes."  There  had  been  no  cut  in  his 
original  estimate;  the  deficiency  was  needed  to  cover  commitments,  the 
department  having  let  contracts  requiring  expenditure  at  a  rate  that  would 
exhaust  the  appropriation  by  April.  When  called  to  explain,  the  Postmaster 
General  replied  that  the  department  had  not  overexpended  its  appropriation 
and  would  not  do  so.  If  the  deficiency  were  not  forthcoming,  the  contracts 
would  be  annulled  and  the  carriage  of  mails  stopped.  The  country  might  be 
inconvenienced,  but  congressional  authorizations  would  not  be  exceeded.43 

The  apportioning  process  is  no  mere  matter  of  dividing  by  four.  Areas 
of  expansion  and  contraction  in  the  agency's  operations  must  be  continu- 
ously reviewed.  To  this  extent  the  justification  process  must  be  repeated 

4234Stat.  48. 

43  Sec  Wilmcrding,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  pp.  137-140. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  605 

in  outline  in  order  to  project  the  agency's  needs  more  realistically  and  with 
closer  precision  against  the  current  record  of  performance.  Apportionments 
may  be  reconsidered  within  the  quarter  as  particular  needs  arise.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  Budget  Bureau  may  go  further  to  protect  the  government 
against  overobligation  or  to  keep  in  the  Treasury  funds  that  appear  to  be 
in  excess  of  actual  requirements  for  the  developing  program  of  an  agency 
by  establishing  reserves  against  appropriations  which  are  withheld  from 
apportionment  altogether. 

This  was  done  on  a  fairly  large  scale  shortly  after  V-J  Day,  before 
Congress  passed  the  Appropriation  Recision  Act44  to  recapture  unused  war 
authorizations.  Of  course,  the  Budget  Bureau's  exercise  of  this  power  may 
raise  delicate  problems  in  executive-legislative  relationships,  especially  if  the 
agency  has  strong  support  in  Congress.  Who  is  the  bureau  to  say  that  the 
agency  may  not  spend  what  the  agency  wants  to  spend  and  Congress  has 
authorized  it  to  spend,  just  because  it  takes  a  different  view  of  the  actual 
sum  required  to  meet  the  legislatively  approved  need?  Statutory  recogni- 
tion of  the  power  to  establish  reserves  has  come  forth  only  quite  recently.45 

Financial  Reporting.  In  connection  with  control  over  apportionments, 
and  in  order  to  provide  the  Treasury  with  current  information  on  the 
status  of  obligations  as  well  as  expenditures,  specific  reporting  machinery 
is  needed.  To  this  end  the  Budget  Bureau  and  the  Treasury  through  joint 
action  have  of  late  elaborated  a  financial  reporting  system,  applicable  to 
all  federal  agencies  and  government  corporations.  Authority  for  this  re- 
form was  supplied  in  Executive  Order  No.  8512  of  August  13,  1940. 

Perhaps  the  most  important  innovation  has  been  the  institution  of  a 
monthly  report  from  the  operating  establishments  on  the  status  of  each  of 
their  appropriations,  showing  unobligated  balances  and  unpaid  obligations. 
The  monthly  status  reports  are  a  substantial  help  in  backing  up  the  appor- 
tionment procedure.  They  sound  a  warning  signal  when  the  rate  of  spend- 
ing and  obligating  threatens  to  run  away  from  the  assumptions  on  which 
the  apportionments  are  based.  Moreover,  the  monthly  status  reports  afford 
another  means  of  comparing  actual  expenditures  with  agency  estimates 
for  the  next  fiscal  year  up  to  the  very  time  that  the  projected  executive 
budget  is  placed  before  the  President. 

Personnel  Ceilings.  A  final  means  of  control  was  recently  established 
when  Congress  singled  out  the  field  of  federal  personnel  for  special  bud- 
getary control.  The  War  Overtime  Pay  Act  of  194346  charged  the  Budget 
Bureau  with  the  duty  of  determining,  from  quarter  to  quarter  and  agency 
by  agency,  the  number  of  employees  necessary  "for  the  proper  and  efficient 
exercise"  of  the  functions  of  the  executive  branch.  The  quarterly  determina- 

44  Act  of  February  18,  1946;  60  Stat.  6. 

45  Sec.  607  of  the  Federal  Employees  Pay  Act  of  June  30,  1945;  59  Stat.  295. 
4«57  Stat.  75. 


606  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

tions  must  be  reported  to  Congress.  These  provisions  of  the  Overtime  Pay 
Act  have  been  made  permanent  legislation.47 

In  order  to  turn  determinations  of  such  character  to  constructive  use, 
they  must  be  paralleled  by  a  program  of  concrete  suggestions  for  manage- 
ment improvement.  This  draws  attention  once  more  to  the  statutory  assign- 
ment of  the  Budget  Bureau  to  strengthen  the  general  organization  and  the 
operating  methods  of  the  executive  branch.  Without  facilities  for  the  con- 
duct of  administrative  studies  as  envisaged  by  the  Budget  and  Accounting 
Act,  the  bureau  would  be  as  ill-equipped  to  set  personnel  ceilings  as  to 
review  estimates  of  expenditures. 

5.  AUDIT 

Public  Finance  and  Representative  Government.  Since  the  seventeenth 
century  it  has  been  an  article  of  faith  among  English-speaking  peoples  that 
legislative  control  of  the  purse-strings  is  the  best  practical  guarantee  of  the 
maintenance  of  representative  government.  The  taming  of  royal  power  in 
England  was  an  institutional  achievement  of  the  legislature.  Fiscal  suprem- 
acy, buttressed  by  the  twin  rights  to  refuse  to  levy  taxes  and  to  refuse  to 
appropriate  their  proceeds  when  levied  as  approved,  was  an  important  in- 
strument in  the  legislature's  success.  From  this  example,  the  American 
colonists  drew  their  basic  lesson. 

Colonial  legislatures  could  not  control  their  appointed  governors  them- 
selves. But  the  lawmaking  bodies  used  their  powers  over  the  sources  and 
uses  of  funds  to  express  their  dissatisfaction  with  the  agents  and  policies 
of  the  home  government.  Frequently  they  elected  their  own  treasurers  in 
order  to  ensure  the  sympathetic  administration  of  their  financial  instructions. 

The  prestige  of  legislatures  was  high  when  the  American  Constitution 
was  adopted.  The  colonists,  on  the  basis  of  their  experience,  had  reason 
to  distrust  every  kind  of  executive  authority.  Little  wonder,  then,  that  the 
framers  of  the  Constitution  put  the  ultimate  authority  over  public  finances 
squarely  in  the  hands  of  the  lawmakers,  and  allotted  to  the  more  popular 
chamber — the  House  of  Representatives — the  prerogative  of  introducing  tax 
bills.  To  this  day,  in  no  field  has  Congress  made  less  use  of  statutory  dele- 
gation, and  kept  the  detailed  exercise  of  its  power  more  jealously  to  itself, 
than  in  the  field  of  taxation. 

Expenditure  Control  in  England.  Legislative  control  of  actual  expendi- 
tures after  appropriations  have  been  voted — keeping  the  spending  of  money 
within  the  scope  of  the  grants  authorized,  checking  the  observance  of  limita- 
tions, and  analyzing  and  appraising  the  results  obtained— has  proved  to  be 
quite  another  matter.  This  was  true  in  England  also  for  a  long  time.  There, 
however,  the  unification  of  the  political  authority  of  both  the  executive  and 
the  legislative  branches  by  means  of  cabinet  government  had  become  so  well 

47  Sec.  607  of  the  Federal  Employees  Pay  Act  of  1945,  cit.  above  in  note  45.  See  also  the 
Federal  Employees  Pay  Act  of  1946,  Public  Law  No.  390,  79th  Cong.,  2d  Scss. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  607 

established  by  the  middle  of  the  last  century  that  a  mutuality  of  interest 
developed  in  an  external,  independent  audit  of  all  financial  transactions. 
This  was  provided  for  by  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Departments  Act  of 
1866.48 

Under  the  law  the  position  of  Comptroller  and  Auditor  General  was 
created,  an  office  to  be  held  "during  good  behavior" — that  is,  on  permanent 
tenure.  With  the  help  of  a  modest  but  expert  staff,  the  incumbent  annually 
examines  the  accounts  of  the  Treasury  and  the  other  departments.  He 
goes  into  such  detail  as  he  finds  necessary  in  view  of  the  internal  administra- 
tive checks  in  operation.  He  ascertains  whether  expenditures  have  been 
kept  within  parliamentary  appropriations,  and  whether  Treasury  directions 
have  been  followed. 

The  Comptroller  and  Auditor  General  reports  his  findings  to  the  Com- 
mittee on  Public  Accounts  of  the  House  of  Commons,  whose  chairman  is 
a  member  of  the  legislative  opposition.  The  committee  first  holds  searching 
hearings  over  these  reports,  attended  by  the  Comptroller  and  Auditor  Gen- 
eral and  by  representatives  of  the  Treasury  and  the  departments  affected. 
Subsequently  the  committee  reports  its  appraisal  and  the  supporting  data  to 
the  House  of  Commons.  In  case  of  legislative  criticism,  the  Treasury  must 
alter  its  practice  or  defend  it  publicly.  Where  expenditures  in  excess  of 
appropriations  have  been  made  by  a  department,  the  Treasury  must  give  its 
sanction  by  authorizing  transfers  of  funds  insofar  as  that  is  permissible;  if  it 
is  not,  the  Treasury  must  secure  a  ratification  from  the  House  of  Commons 
in  the  form  of  a  supplementary  appropriation.  If  neither  course  prevails, 
the  departmental  accounting  officer  is  held  personally  liable. 

Under  this  system  there  is  public  assurance  that  financial  policies  and 
procedures  will  stand  disinterested  scrutiny,  without  calling  in  question 
the  major  substantive  decisions  for  which  the  government  assumes  political 
responsibility.  A  roughly  similar  result  is  aimed  at  under  modern  practice 
by  the  independent  audit  of  private  corporations  whose  securities  are  pub- 
licly traded,  in  line  with  requirements  of  the  stock  exchanges  and  of  the 
Securities  and  Exchange  Commission.  However,  the  position  of  minority 
investors  in  relation  to  corporate  management  is  obviously  much  weaker 
than  that  of  the  House  of  Commons.  As  a  result  the  degree  of  disclosure  to 
them—and  the  corresponding  influence  of  possible  publicity  on  corporate 
practices — is  distinctly  smaller. 

Beginnings  of  Expenditure  Control  in  the  United  States.  The  separation 
of  powers  embodied  in  American  government  has  so  far  precluded  any  such 
amicably  efficacious  arrangement  for  legislative  control  of  public  expendi- 
tures as  we  find  in  England.  Once  the  appropriation  acts  have  been  passed, 
the  use  of  funds  is  in  administrative  hands.  To  be  sure,  the  process  of  ad- 
ministrative spending  is  one  in  which  individual  legislators  often  share  as 

48  29  &  30  Viet.,  ch.  39. 


608  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

they  pursue  particular  interests  such  as  an  allocation  for  public  works  or 
the  location  of  a  field  installation.49  Yet  no  full-fledged  audit  brings  back 
to  the  lawmaking  body  an  independent  review  of  what  has  transpired. 

No  specific  machinery  exists  by  which  the  legislature  can  systematically 
hold  officials  accountable  for  their  expenditures.  Beset  with  divided  counsel 
and  conflicting  interests  among  its  own  membership,  preoccupied  most  of 
the  time  with  other  matters,  virtually  paralyzed  by  the  enormous  mass  of 
its  business,  and  confronted  with  a  chief  executive  who  does  not  depend 
on  its  pleasure  for  office,  Congress  has  delegated  or  left  unexercised  nearly 
all  of  its  authority  in  expenditure  control.  For  the  most  part  it  confines  itself 
to  taking  into  account  in  succeeding  appropriations  what  it  has  learned — 
however  imperfectly — about  the  use  of  the  last. 

This  does  not  mean,  of  course,  that  we  lack  in  the  United  States  a  system 
of  expenditure  control  and  fiscal  accountability.  Its  roots  run  back  through 
time  to  the  revolutionary  governments  preceding  the  adoption  of  the  Ameri- 
can Constitution.  From  1789  to  1921  Congress  relied  on  two  main  devices 
of  surveillance,  supplemented  occasionally  by  committee  investigations. 
These  were:  (1)  the  language  of  the  appropriation  acts;  and  (2)  a  set  of 
internal  checks  within  the  executive  branch.  The  descriptive  language 
would  set  forth  with  more  or  less  particularity  the  purposes  of  the  individual 
appropriation.  The  internal  administrative  checks  were  designed  to  ensure 
that  at  each  stage  in  the  spending  process  a  separate  official  was  responsible 
for  attesting  the  integrity  of  the  transaction — too  many  officials  in  all,  and 
too  divergent  in  interests,  to  make  collusion  practicable. 

Specificity  of  Appropriations.  Reliance  on  qualifying  language  to  govern 
administrative  spending  led  to  the  doctrine  of  specific  appropriations.  The 
act  of  March  3,  1809,  laid  down  the  injunction,  still  in  effect,  that  "the  sums 
appropriated  by  law  for  each  branch  of  expenditure  in  the  several  depart- 
ments shall  be  solely  applied  to  the  objects  for  which  they  are  respectively 
appropriated,  and  to  no  other."50  This  was  coupled  with  a  policy  and  prac- 
tice of  specifying  objects  of  expenditure  minutely.  The  development  of 
excessive  specificity  was  an  inevitable  outgrowth  and  in  the  end  proved 
self-defeating. 

The  earliest  appropriation  for  the  support  of  the  government,  in  1789, 
was  simple  enough.  In  one  hundred  twenty-three  words  it  disposed  of  $639,- 
000  under  four  headings.  The  amounts  were  derived  from  estimates  fur- 
nished by  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  Alexander  Hamilton.  A  little  expe- 
rience in  the  method  of  deficiency  requests  to  cover  objects  thought  to  have 
been  already  provided  for  soon  showed  that  there  was  no  necessary  restric- 
tive connection  between  prior  estimates  of  expenditure  and  the  actual  use 
made  of  available  funds. 

49  Sec  above  Ch.  15,  "Legislative  Control." 

00  Rev.  Stat.,  sec.  3678,  31  U.  S.  C.  628.  The  history  of  congressional  efforts  to  control 
expenditures  has  been  traced  with  insight  and  charm  by  Wilmcrding,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  39. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  609 

Under  the  sting  of  criticism  from  Gallatin  and  Jefferson,  the  Federalists 
gradually  accepted  a  greater  specification  of  objects.  This  was  softened,  how- 
ever, by  a  delegation  of  power  to  the  President  to  authorize  certain  transfers 
between  appropriation  headings  when  Congress  was  not  in  session.  As 
party  control  of  the  government  shifted,  so  did  the  points  of  view.  But  the 
trend  toward  particularization  continued.  Nevertheless,  within  a  generation 
theory  and  practice  were  no  longer  within  speaking  distance  of  each  other. 

Appropriations  were  specified  in  the  minutest  detail.  However,  by  means 
of  transfers,  the  carrying  forward  of  unexpended  balances,  and  the  incur- 
ring of  obligations  in  anticipation  of  deficiency  appropriations — all  in  the 
teeth  of  statutes  designed  to  prevent  these  practices — funds  were  found  for 
expenditures  the  departments  wanted  to  make  beyond  the  original  appropria- 
tions. John  Randolph  in  1806  expressed  the  feeling  of  congressional  helpless- 
ness when,  though  in  opposition,  he  refused  to  try  to  reduce  the  naval  ap- 
propriation for  contingent  expenses:  "If  we  cannot  restrain  the  expenditures 
of  the  Navy  Department  within  the  sum  annually  fixed,  after  giving  as 
much  as  is  asked  for,  is  it  not  the  idlest  thing  to  attempt  to  restrain  them 
by  giving  less?"51  We  may  also  think  of  the  anecdote  related  by  Henry 
Clay  in  1819  to  show  how  institutional  frustration  turned  into  individual 
cynicism:52 

Some  years  ago  it  had  been  the  custom,  now  abolished,  to  use  in  this 
House  a  beverage  in  lieu  of  water  for  those  members  who  preferred  it. 
A  member  of  the  House  said  he  was  not  in  the  habit  of  using  this  sort 
of  substitute  for  one  of  nature's  greatest  and  purest  bounties,  but  would 
prefer  something  stronger.  The  officers  of  the  House  said  they  should  be 
glad  to  gratify  him,  but  did  not  know  how  they  could  with  propriety  pay 
for  it  out  of  the  contingent  fund.  Why,  said  the  member,  under  what 
head  of  appropriation  do  you  pay  for  this  syrup  for  the  use  of  the  mem- 
bers? Under  the  head  of  stationery,  the  officer  said.  Well,  replied  the 
member,  put  down  a  little  grog  under  the  head  of  fuel,  and  let  me 
have  it. 

By  the  latter  part  of  the  nineteenth  century,  Congress  had  come  to  ap- 
preciate fully  the  realities  of  the  situation.  It  often  appropriated  deliberately 
less  money  than  was  known  to  be  required,  with  the  expectation  of  provid- 
ing the  remainder  in  deficiency  bills  later.  In  even-numbered  years  the 
legislature  was  tempted  to  take  advantage  of  this  technique  to  make  a  show 
of  economy.  It  was  not  until  the  beginning  of  genuine  budgetary  practice 
under  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921  that  the  conduct  of  federal 
administration  was  freed  from  the  irrationalities  of  such  coercive  deficiencies. 

Administrative  Checks.  The  internal  checks  that  were  devised  also 
showed  themselves  unsatisfactory.  The  Treasury  Department  Act  of  1789 
established  under  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  a  comptroller,  a  treasurer, 
an  auditor,  and  a  register-keeping  officer.  According  to  the  underlying  theory, 

61  Annals  of  Congress,  Vol.  15,  p.  1000;  Wilmerding,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  p.  66. 
52  Annals  of  Congress,  Vol.  33,  p.  456;  Wilmerding,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  p.  82. 


610  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

when  Congress  had  passed  an  appropriation  for  the  use  of  a  particular 
department  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  drew  a  "warrant,"  and  the  comp- 
troller countersigned  it.  This  established  an  appropriation  credit  with  the 
treasurer,  which  the  register-keeping  officer  recorded.  Thereafter,  until  the 
credit  was  exhausted,  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  on  request  of  the  de- 
partment, would  issue  further  warrants  in  favor  of  particular  payees,  which 
the  treasurer  would  pay  upon  countersignature  by  the  comptroller. 

The  request  might  take  the  form  of  a  voucher  for  materials  received  or 
services  performed;  if  so,  it  had  first  to  be  examined  and  approved — or 
"settled" — by  the  auditor  and  the  comptroller.  Commonly,  however,  the  pay- 
ment was  an  advance  of  funds  to  a  departmental  agent — or  disbursing  offi- 
cer— who  then  proceeded  to  pay  vouchers  approved  in  the  department.  Be- 
cause of  the  particularity  of  appropriations,  disbursing  officers  usually  held 
advances  under  several  separate  appropriation  headings.  Many  of  these 
officers,  especially  in  the  revenue  and  postal  services,  were  also  collectors  of 
public  funds.  For  both  these  reasons  they  were  frequently,  in  a  position,  if 
their  advances  under  a  particular  heading  were  exhausted,  to  borrow  tem- 
porarily from  another  to  meet  the  need  for  an  immediate  payment. 

The  disbursing  officers  were  accountable  to  the  auditor,  and  furnished 
him  periodic  reports  listing  their  collections  and  advances,  and  their  pay- 
ments supported  by  paid  vouchers.  If  the  auditor  disallowed  a  payment  as 
unauthorized  under  the  appropriation  charged  and  the  comptroller  sustained 
him,  the  disbursing  officer  was  personally  liable.  If  he  could  not  clear  the 
disallowance  by  supplying  further  information,  by  charging  the  expenditure 
to  another  appropriation,  by  recovering  the  money  from  the  payee,  or  by 
securing  a  relief  act  from  Congress,  he  was  bound  to  pay  it  himself.  If  he 
defaulted,  the  comptroller — later  the  Solicitor,  and  now  the  Department  of 
Justice — was  charged  with  the  duty  of  collecting  the  debt. 

Some  experience  with  the  latitude  of  personal  responsibility  of  disbursing 
officers  led  to  the  requirement  that  they  be  bonded.  This  requirement  has 
lately  been  extended  to  the  certifying  officers,  who  approve  vouchers,53  in 
view  of  the  mechanized  and  ministerial  nature  of  the  disbursing  officers' 
duties  under  modern  conditions.  Moreover,  as  a  part  of  their  operating 
routine  the  departments  and  bureaus  developed  their  own  internal  checks 
on  the  accounts  of  their  disbursing  officers  before  transmittal  to  the  Treas- 
ury. The  settled  accounts  went  to  the  Treasury,  and  remained  there.  In 
theory,  an  analysis  of  them,  together  with  the  warrants  issued  directly,  would 
have  made  it  possible  to  determine,  as  of  any  given  date,  the  status  and  uses 
of  an  appropriation.  In  fact,  however,  such  information  was  never  assem- 
bled in  time  to  serve  any  comprehensive  budgetary  or  reporting  purpose. 

Delay  and  Laxity.  Some  frailties  of  this  system  are  plain,  of  which  the 
chief  was  its  delays.  As  a  critic  remarked,  the  system  was  "the  most  admir- 

M  Act  of  December  29,  1941;  55  Stat.  875. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  611 

able  contrivance  that  the  mind  of  man  ever  conceived  to  put  down  the  sums 
claimed  by  public  creditors  to  the  smallest  figures,  and  then  to  postpone  to  the 
latest  possible  moment  the  payment  of  what  has  at  last  been  acknowledged 
due."54  However,  First  Comptroller  Elisha  Whittlesey,  when  asked  by  Sec- 
retary of  the  Treasury  Guthrie  in  1854  to  report  improvements,  responded 
in  the  sentiment  that  sustained  the  system  through  the  nineteenth  century: 
"The  law  organizing  the  Treasury  Department . . .  was  framed  by  very  wise 
men,  who  took  a  deep  interest  in  the  welfare  and  prosperity  of  the  country. 
The  system  is  based  on  checks  to  guard  against  dishonesty  and  fraud,  and 
it  has  worked  admirably.  The  Treasury  Department  is  as  pure  and  free 
from  the  perpetration  of  fraud  as  it  was  the  day  it  went  into  operation.  .  .  . 
The  system,  in  my  opinion,  cannot  be  bettered,  and  operates  as  harmoniously 
and  beautifully  now,  as  it  did  sixty-five  years  ago."55 

In  theory,  the  chain  of  fiscal  accountability  began  with  an  appropriation. 
But  in  the  old  days  Congress  was  not — as  it  is  now — in  virtually  continuous 
session;  distances  were  great,  and  communications  uncertain  and  slow.  Just 
as  the  specification  of  appropriations  annulled  its  purpose  by  its  rigidity  in 
the  face  of  unforeseeable  changes  in  conditions  and  needs,  so  the  administra- 
tive checks  and  balances  turned  into  impediments  when  they  prevented 
payments  that  had  to  be  made  within  a  time  limit  to  serve  their  end — food 
and  forage  for  troops  and  animals  on  a  western  expedition,  provisions  for 
vessels  about  to  sail,  payment  to  France  for  the  Louisiana  Purchase,  for  ex- 
ample. The  exigencies  of  government  were  at  the  paying,  not  the  appro- 
priating, end  of  the  chain. 

In  an  effort  to  meet  the  complaints  about  delays,  the  duties  of  the  comp- 
troller and  the  auditor  were  splintered  at  an  early  date.  By  1836  there  were 
six  auditors  and  two  comptrollers;  yet  the  tempo  was  not  quickened.  As  an 
unavoidable  result,  the  actual  sequence  of  events  was  as  likely  as  not  to 
start  with  a  payment  by  a  disbursing  officer,  leaving  the  train  of  authorizing 
warrants  and  appropriations  to  follow  along  by  way  of  ratification.  When 
this  was  a  common  occurrence,  it  is  understandable  why  promptness  and 
exacting  standards  in  the  settlement  of  accounts  were  hard  to  obtain. 

Failure  to  secure  dispatch  and  meticulous  procedure,  however,  was  dis- 
astrous to  the  Treasury's  own  accounting  system.  It  could  tell  quickly 
enough  what  appropriations  had  been  made,  what  advances  had  been  issued, 
and  what  receipts  had  been  reported.  On  the  other  hand,  everything  else 
was  at  large— what  obligations  had  been  incurred  or  were  in  prospect,  at 
what  rate  advances  would  be  spent,  what  payments  and  receipts  were  not 
yet  reported,  what  reported  payments  would  be  disallowed.  All  of  this  had 
to  wait  on  paperwork  that  would  spread  over  the  ensuing  years.  On  this 
footing  of  sand  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  reported  annually  to  Con- 

MRenick,  Edward  I.,  "Control  of  National  Expenditures,"  Political  Science  Quarterly,  1891, 
Vol.  6,  p.  248. 

55  Annual  Report  of  the  First  Comptroller,  1854,  pp.  103-104. 


612  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

grass  on  the  state  of  federal  finances.  It  was  an  inescapable  consequence  that 
Congress  could  bring  only  a  dusty  vision  to  the  business  of  taxing,  bor- 
rowing, and  appropriating. 

Path  of  Reform.  Modern  efforts  to  reform  the  system  began  with  the 
Dockery  Act  of  1894,66  the  collaborative  work  of  Secretary  of  the  Treasury 
Foster  and  a  congressional  commission,  aided  by  outside  experts.  It  clarified 
the  jurisdiction  of  the  auditors,  and  strengthened  their  supervision  over  dis- 
bursing officers  as  well  as  over  the  issuance  of  departmental  requisitions  for 
advances.  The  law  consolidated  the  comptrollers  into  one,  as  in  the  insti- 
tutional beginning,  with  appellate  authority  over  the  auditors.  It  made  it 
the  comptroller's  duty  to  render  advance  decisions  on  request  from  depart- 
ment heads  or  disbursing  officers,  and  gave  him  power  to  prescribe  the 
forms  of  keeping  and  rendering  all  public  accounts.  Finally,  the  new  legis- 
lation centralized  all  bookkeeping  in  the  Treasury  in  a  reorganized  Divi- 
sion of  Warrants,  Estimates  and  Appropriations— displacing  this  kind  of 
work  of  the  register-keeping  officer  and  the  auditors. 

Under  the  dispensation  of  1894,  the  comptroller's  main  function  was  to 
provide  a  uniform  construction  of  the  appropriation  laws,  conclusive  and 
binding  upon  all  the  departments.  There  had  been  earlier  conflict  over  the 
finality  of  determinations  by  department  heads  when  challenged  by  the 
comptroller,  as  happened  on  occasion.  The  Dockery  Act  did  not  touch  this 
ambiguity,  which  entered  the  picture  especially  whenever  the  comptroller 
asked  the  Attorney  General  to  collect  by  suit  a  payment  disallowed  on  a 
construction  of  the  law  by  the  comptroller  that  the  Attorney  General  dis- 
agreed with.57  As  to  the  comptroller's  status,  although  he  and  the  auditors 
arere  subordinates  of  the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  the  spoils  system — as 
a  rule  with  relatively  few  exceptions — yielded  far  enough  to  keep  them  in 
office  with  successive  changes  in  the  political  control  of  the  govern- 
ment. Of  course,  like  other  bureau  chiefs,  they  were  ordinarily  patronage 
appointees  in  the  earlier  period. 

It  was  at  this  stage  of  development  that  the  movement  leading  to  the 
passage  of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  of  1921  overtook  the  accounting 
system  of  the  government.  It  was  by  then  a  system  that  imposed  on  each 
individual  disbursing  officer  a  tiresomely  detailed  and  long  drawn-out  ac- 
countability to  Treasury  officials  for  every  payment  made,  applying  the  test 
of  statutory  authorization  onlv,  and  seemingly  unconcerned  with  administra- 
tive results  ach'Vvrrl  or  operating  standards  applied.  It  put  almost  no  organi- 
zational resoonsibility  on  the  departments  and  bureaus  for  the  effective 
handling  of  their  fiscal  affairs.  This  was  the  more  serious  because,  until 

MAct  of  July  31,  1894;  28  Stat  162,  205.  For  the  report  of  the  Dockery  Commission 
and  the  debate  in  the  House  of  Representatives,  see  Congressional  Record,  Vol.  26,  pp.  4297- 
4307,  4335-4354. 

W  See  Mansfield,  Harvey  C.,  The  Comptroller  General,  ch.  4,  New  Haven:  Yale  Uni- 
versity Press,  1939. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  613 

the  recent  emergence  of  departmental  management  in  a  fairly  inclusive 
sense,  all  the  bureaus  were  nearly  autonomous  operating  entities. 

Equally  important,  the  accounting  system  left  the  Treasury,  as  the  cen- 
tral fiscal  agency  of  the  government,  and  a  fortiori  also  Congress,  without 
any  adequate  current  and  comprehensive  conception  of  the  over-all  finan- 
cial situation.  Except  for  occasional  and  sporadic  legislative  intervention, 
the  system  reserved  for  the  executive  branch  all  administrative  determina- 
tions as  to  how  and  whether  congressional  mandates  attached  to  appropria- 
tions were  observed.  While  this  would  have  been  a  proper  arrangement  if 
bolstered  by  some  kind  of  subsequent  review,  there  was  actually  no  provi- 
sion whatever  for  securing  to  Congress  the  benefits  of  an  independent 
inquiry  and  opinion  on  such  matters.  True,  these  are  hindsight  judgments. 
In  the  light  of  contemporary  opinion,  and  in  the  absence  of  the  financial 
strains  under  which  European  governments  operated,  the  system  was  not 
viewed  with  any  marked  dissatisfaction  in  the  country. 

Formation  of  the  General  Accounting  Office.  The  Budget  and  Account- 
ing Act  of  1921  made  two  important  changes  in  the  scheme  of  financial 
accountability,  one  of  them  fundamental.  First,  it  rolled  together  into  a 
single  establishment  the  combined  functions,  personnel,  and  records  of  the 
former  comptroller  and  the  six  auditors,  without  modifying  substantially  the 
definitions  of  basic  powers  and  duties  as  these  had  developed  over  the  years. 
This  new  establishment  was  the  General  Accounting  Office,  under  a  single 
head — the  Comptroller  General.  Second,  the  act  described  the  General  Ac- 
counting Office  as  "independent  of  the  executive  departments."  This  theory 
was  reinforced  by  the  stipulation  that  the  functions  of  the  General  Account- 
ing Office  be  performed  "without  direction  from  any  other  officer."  As  a 
tangible  institutional  guarantee  of  independence,  the  act  gave  the  Comp- 
troller General  a  fifteen-year  term  of  office,  making  him  irremovable  except 
by  joint  resolution  of  Congress  for  cause  and  after  hearing. 

Adoption  by  Congress  of  Title  HI  of  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act, 
containing  these  changes,  was  not  preceded  by  any  real  debate  of  its  provi- 
sions,  except  for  the  question  of  the  Comptroller  General's  tenure.  The 
fifteen-year  term  was  a  compromise  between  the  views  of  the  House  leader- 
ship intent  upon  an  indefinite  term— "during  good  behavior"— and  the  Sen- 
ators who  wanted  one  of  seven  years.  The  House  also  talked  of  vesting 
the  appointment  in  Congress.  However,  it  was  deterred  by  the  argument 
that,  since  one  Congress  could  not  bind  the  next,  a  maximum  term  of  only 
two  years  could  be  assured  that  way. 

Before  the  bill  finally  passed  there  was  an  unsuccessful  move  to  hand 
the  power  of  appointment  to  the  Supreme  Court.  Although  emphatically 
in  favor  of  the  reform  measure,  President  Wilson  in  1920  vetoed  the  bill  as 
originally  passed.  He  protested  that  the  restriction  on  his  removal  power 
was  unconstitutional— a  question  the  legislative  arrangement  was  designed 
to  avoid.  But  when  the  law  was  repassed  the  next  year  with  only  a  slight 


614  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

and  hardly  consequential  change,  President  Harding  accepted  it.  The  cpn- 
stitutional  point  is  likely  to  remain  moot.58 

When  voting  on  the  law,  few  members  of  Congress  realized  that  the 
establishment  of  an  independent  General  Accounting  Office  was  simply 
creating  a  separation  of  powers  within  the  administrative  structure  as  com- 
plete and  thorough  as  that  prevailing  in  the  constitutional  system.  This  took 
the  place  of  the  former  division  of  labor  that  afforded  internal  checks  in  an 
administration  ultimately  responsible  to  the  President.  The  proponents  of 
the  new  scheme,  experts  and  Congressmen  alike,  had  talked  of  the  need  for 
an  "independent"  audit  on  behalf  of  Congress— and  frequently  invoked  the 
English  example  in  complete  misunderstanding  of  its  most  basic  features. 
What  the  act  in  fact  did  was  to  institute  an  independent  administrative 
control  over  expenditures,  exercised  from  the  standpoint  of  their  legality. 

Control  Versus  Audit.  The  distinction  is  basic.  The  important  power  of 
the  Comptroller  General,  as  of  the  comptroller  before  him,  is  to  "settle" 
accounts.  Settlement  has  always  meant,  as  Wilmerding  puts  it,  "the  final 
administrative  determination  of  the  balances  due  to  or  from  the  United 
States  on  accounts  between  itself  and  its  debtors  and  creditors."59  An  audit, 
on  the  other  hand,  is  "an  examination  made  on  behalf  of  a  principal  of  the 
transactions  of  an  agent  as  recorded  in  an  account."00  The  Comptroller  Gen- 
eral conducts  an  examination  of  the  payments  made  by  administrative  offi- 
cers, not  on  behalf  of  Congress  but  as  an  incident  to  the  exercise  of  his 
power  as  a  principal  to  settle  accounts.  He  also  determines  the  amounts  to 
be  paid  on  claims  submitted  to  his  office  for  direct  settlement.  No  one 
makes  an  audit  report  to  Congress  of  the  amounts  finally  allowed  as  charges 
against  appropriations;  and  the  Comptroller  General  would  be  the  last  per- 
son suitable  to  do  so,  since  he  himself  makes  the  determinations  that  would 
be  reviewed  in  such  an  audit. 

The  effects  of  this  confusion  of  audit  and  control  are  apparent  in  two 
directions — on  accountability  to  the  legislature,  and  on  the  conduct  of  ad- 
ministration. On  the  legislative  side,  the  existence  of  the  Comptroller  Gen- 
eral has  given  Congress  a  comforting  and  illusory  sense  of  security.  After 
all,  somebody  is  looking  after  the  matter,  and  nothing  more  needs  to  be 
done.  This  conclusion  would  be  warranted  only  on  the  supposition  that  the 
Comptroller  General  is  infallible.  In  fact,  after  one  hundred  sixty  years, 
Congress  still  has  no  regular  and  comprehensive  means  of  knowing  how  far 
its  fiscal  mandates  and  limitations  are  being  observed. 

By  the  same  token,  the  legislature  has  set  up  no  machinery  in  the  nature 
of  a  public-accounts  committee  to  provide  an  orderly  instrument  for  making 
use  of  pertinent  information  for  control  purposes.  In  1920  the  Senate,  and 

58  Sec  Mansfield,  op.  cit.  above  in  note  57,  ch.  3. 

**0p.  cit.  above  in  note  39,  p.  259.  For  a  convincing  development  of  this  point,  see 
ibid.,  ch.  12. 

.  273. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  615 

in  1927  the  House,  adopted  resolutions  consolidating  their  several  previous 
committees  on  appropriations  in  the  executive  departments  into  one  each. 
The  evidence  is  clear,  however,  that  both  committees  have  been  generally 
inactive  in  the  area  of  fiscal  accountability — rather  completely  so  in  the  Sen- 
ate, and  in  the  House  confined  to  occasional  investigations  of  specific  com- 
plaints. A  lawmaking  body  needs  staff  assistance  in  so  intricate  a  field  as 
financial  control.  While  this  general  proposition  has  been  gaining  some  ac- 
ceptance in  connection  with  the  legislative  consideration  of  the  budget,  it 
has  made  little  headway  as  applied  to  control  based  on  audit. 

In  the  conduct  of  public  management,  the  strictures  imposed  by  the 
separation  of  powers  within  the  administrative  structure  have  been  produc- 
tive of  much  controversy.  This  was  true  particularly  under  the  regime  of 
Comptroller  General  McCarl  that  spanned  most  of  the  period  from  1921 
until  World  War  II.  The  policy  of  the  General  Accounting  Office  dictated 
expansion.  The  scope  of  its  review  widened  considerably.  Increasingly  it 
substituted  its  determinations  for  those  of  operating  officials  on  questions  of 
fact  as  well  as  of  law  involved  in  ruling  on  the  availability  of  appropriations.01 
The  adoption  of  rules  and  forms  was  designed  to  bring  to  the  General 
Accounting  Office  a  much  greater  proportion  of  the  immense  mass  of  under- 
lying data  on  which  its  determinations  are  based.  Moreover,  the  depart- 
ments were  urged— and  legislation  was  unsuccessfully  sought  to  compel 
them — to  submit  their  vouchers  for  preaudit  in  advance  of  payment.  This 
invitation  was  accepted  in  only  a  very  small  proportion  of  the  total  volume 
of  transactions. 

The  immediate  consequences  of  all  these  policies  were  to  draw  attention 
to  arguments  over  jurisdiction  and  to  paperwork  about  details  handled  at  a 
point  too  remote  from  their  operating  origin,  to  the  detriment  of  good 
management.  It  soon  became  apparent  also  that  the  Comptroller  General's 
independence  left  a  good  deal  of  room  within  the  interstices  of  the  law  for 
the  expression  of  views  on  public  policy  in  social  and  economic  fields.  Such 
expressions  did  not  necessarily  coincide  with  prevailing  attitudes  in  either 
the  executive  or  the  legislative  branch.  The  Comptroller  General  tangled 
early  with  Congress  over  veterans'  payments,  and  later  with  the  executive 
branch  over  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority62  and  other  New  Deal  measures. 

Safeguarding  Operational  Responsibility.  One  by-product  was  no  doubt 
a  stimulus  to  the  improvement  of  Treasury  accounting63  and  the  develop- 
ment of  departmental  management  in  order  to  meet  more  effectively  the 

61 A  large  body  of  case  law  has  been  built  up  in  this  field.  Annual  increments  will  be 
found  in  the  published  volumes  of  the  decisions  of  the  Comptroller  General. 

**2On  the  relationship  between  the  Comptroller  General  and  government  corporations  in 
general,  sec  above  Ch.  11,  "Government  Corporations,"  sec.  3,  "Overhead  Control  of  Cor- 
porate Operations."  See  also  McDiarmid,  John,  Government  Corporations  and  Federal  Funds. 
Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press,  1938. 

68  See  Bartelt,  Edward  F.,  Accounting  Procedures  of  the  United  States  Government, 
Chicago:  Public  Administration  Service,  1940. 


6l6  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

Comptroller  General's  encroachments  on  operating  discretion.  In  addition, 
his  restrictive  approach  furnished  a  marked  impetus  to  both  the  establish- 
ment of  agencies  and  the  organization  of  activities  in  corporate  form  out- 
side his  purview.  A  further  method  of  mitigating  his  influence  was  the 
enactment  of  legislation  specifically  making  the  findings  of  particular  agency 
heads  on  particular  types  of  questions  conclusive  on  the  Comptroller  General. 
In  this  fashion  the  bulk  of  payments  in  World  War  II  was  made  subject 
to  his  scrutiny  only  in  very  limited  degrees  or  not  at  all.  On  a  direct  test 
of  the  central  issue  he  was  expressly  foreclosed  from  reviewing  war-contract 
termination  payments,  except  on  the  narrowest  grounds,  by  the  Contract 
Settlement  Act  of  1944.  Here  effective  use  was  made  in  debate  of  the  pros- 
pects of  delay  and  of  "unemployment  by  audit,"  if  the  Comptroller  General 
were  permitted  to  question  the  bases  of  settlements  previously  arrived  at.84 
This  prohibition  operated  to  throw  out  baby  and  bath  together — the  scope 
of  the  audit  would  not  reach  beyond  the  settlement  which  represented  the 
terminal  point  of  a  complex  series  of  prior  transactions. 

Recognizing  the  undesirability  of  the  general  state  of  affairs,  and  recap- 
turing some  of  the  ground  previously  yielded  to  executive  freedom  of  action, 
Congress  undertook  to  push  in  a  different  direction  in  passing  the  Govern- 
ment Corporation  Control  Act  of  1945.05  Statutory  precedents  for  this  ven- 
ture existed  in  the  instructions  given  the  Comptroller  General  to  audit,  but 
not  to  settle,  the  accounts  of  the  Shipping  Board  and  the  Emergency  Fleet 
Corporation  after  World  War  I,  and  also  of  the  Tennessee  Valley  Authority 
under  its  basic  statute  of  1933.66  But  Comptroller  General  McCarl  had 
made  these  instructions  instruments  of  controversy  rather  than  of  construc- 
ive  innovation.  In  addition  to  preventing  the  establishment  of  new  govern- 
ment corporations  without  express  statutory  sanction  in  the  future,  the 
Government  Corporation  Control  Act  directed  the  Comptroller  General  to 
conduct  a  commercial  type  of  audit  of  each  of  the  existing  corporations  to 
be  considered  permanent,  giving  due  recognition  to  their  needs  for  operating 
flexibility.  The  results  he  is  to  report  to  Congress.  All  corporate  transac- 
tions were  opened  to  his  examination,  but  he  was  given  no  power  to  settle 
the  accounts. 

It  is  too  soon  to  appraise  this  experiment  in  'echniques  of  accountability. 
Much  will  depend  on  the  spirit  in  which  the  Comptroller  General  ap- 
proaches his  task,  and  on  the  degree  of  cooperation  he  receives  from  public 
enterprises  previously  exempt  and  taught  by  experience  to  be  suspicious  of 
his  activities.  On  the  first  score,  the  Comptroller  General's  initial  selection 
of  an  informed  and  outspoken  critic  of  previous  procedures  to  head  the  new 

w  See  Key,,  V.  O.,  'The  Reconversion  Phase  of  Demobilization,"  American  Political  Science 
Review,  1944,  Vol.  38,  p.  1146  ff. 

'6559  Star.  597.  Sec  also  above  Ch.  11,  "Government  Corporations,"  sec.  3,  "Overhead 
Control  of  Corporate  Operations." 

««48Stat.  58. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  617 

operation  is  a  good  omen.  If  coperation  is  forthcoming,  the  next  test  will 
be  for  Congress  to  show  its  statesmanship  in  the  use  of  a  new  tool.  If 
good  results  are  obtained,  conceivably  a  model  is  indicated  for  eventual 
extension  to  the  regular  departments. 

Balance  Sheet  of  Audit  and  Settlement  of  Accounts.  From  this  review 
it  is  apparent  that  as  matters  stand  the  pattern  of  accountability  for  the  use 
of  public  funds  after  they  have  been  spent  is  exceedingly  uneven,  depending 
in  part  on  the  historical  position  of  the  individual  agency  and  in  part  on 
its  current  favor  with  Congress.  If  the  agency  is  in  the  old-line  tradition, 
it  must  submit  its  vouchers  for  settlement,  accompanied  by  elaborate  sup- 
porting data  from  which  the  Comptroller  General  will  draw  his  own  con- 
clusions. Or,  if — as  in  the  case  of  veterans'  payments — Congress  really  wants 
its  funds  to  get  out  to  the  payees  promptly  without  haggling  after  the  event, 
the  vouchers  will  be  submitted.  However,  they  will  be  accompanied  by  cer- 
tificates of  findings  that  shut  out  review  in  the  absence  of  evidence  of 
fraud.  If  the  establishment  in  question  is  a  corporation,  its  books  must  be 
open  to  examination,  but  no  accounts  will  be  submitted  for  settlement. 
In  all  three  situations,  accountability  is  as  yet  to  the  General  Accounting 
Office,  not  to  the  legislature. 

Appraising  the  experience  from  1921  to  1936,  the  President's  Committee 
on  Administrative  Management  in  1937  proposed  a  reorganization  of  fiscal 
administration,  based  on  the  divorce  of  the  Comptroller  General's  audit  and 
settlement  powers67  and  the  establishment  of  accountability  to  Congress 
through  a  Joint  Committee  on  Public  Accounts.  Under  the  House  and 
Senate  bills  introduced  to  give  effect  to  these  recommendations,  the  control 
powers  proper  were  variously  assigned  to  the  Treasury  and  the  Budget 
Bureau.  The  Senate  passed  its  bill,  but  the  House  bill  was  recommitted 
by  a  narrow  vote  in  the  aftermath  of  the  defeat  of  the  President's  plan  for 
reconstructing  the  Supreme  Court.  The  Reorganization  Act  of  1939  left 
the  whole  matter  untouched.  In  the  Reorganization  Act  of  1945,  Congress 
made  plain  its  intent  to  preclude  any  changes  affecting  the  status  of  the 
General  Accounting  Office  by  means  of  the  reorganization  plans  it  author- 
ized the  President  to  submit. 

However,  the  subject  was  reopened  in  the  hearings  held  in  1945  by  the 
Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Congress.  The  committee  adopted 
several  proposals  specifically  intended  to  strengthen  fiscal  control  on  the 
part  of  the  legislature  itself.68  These  proposals  deal  with  both  the  budget 
process  and  the  character  of  the  Comptroller  General's  audit  functions 
In  certain  ways  they  appear  to  represent  a  tour  de  force  that  could  have 
dubious  consequences.  However,  while  some  of  the  recommendations  may 
prove  excessively  restrictive  and  to  that  extent  not  conducive  to  responsible 

67  See  President's  Committee  on  Administrative  Management,  Report  with  Special  Studies 
p.  15  ff.,  49  ff.,  139  ff.,  173  ff.,  Washington:  Government  Printing  Office,  1937. 

68  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  18  ff. 


618  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

financial  management,  others  demonstrate  a  welcome  tendency  toward 
broadening  the  range  of  congressional  information  about  the  way  appro- 
priations are  being  spent.  Perhaps  the  most  serious  objection  that  may  be 
raised  to  the  proposals  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization  of  Con- 
gress is  that  they  are  on  the  whole  rather  heavy-handed—explained  in  part 
no  doubt  by  the  cumulative  effect  of  legislative  frustrations  over  a  long 
period.  Although  some  of  the  proposals  have  been  referred  to  earlier  in 
the  particular  context  of  our  discussion,  it  may  be  convenient  at  this  point 
to  summarize  them  in  the  order  in  which  they  have  been  set  forth  by  the 
committee. 

The  first  recommendation  stipulates  that,  within  the  initial  sixty  days 
of  each  congressional  session  or  by  April  15,  the  revenue  and  appropriations 
committees  of  both  chambers  by  joint  action  submit  to  Congress  a  concur- 
rent resolution — not  sent  to  the  President  for  approval  or  veto — set- 
ting over-all  receipts  and  expenditures  for  the  coming  fiscal  year.  If  esti- 
mated revenue  does  not  measure  up  to  proposed  expenditure,  Congress  by  a 
record  vote  must  authorize  a  corresponding  increase  in  the  national  debt. 
Should  actual  appropriations  exceed  the  approved  budget  figure,  each  ap- 
propriation would  be  reduced  by  a  uniform  percentage,  except  those  of  a 
permanent  nature,  interest  on  the  national  debt,  veterans'  pensions  and 
benefits,  trust  expenditures,  and  debt  retirement. 

The  second  recommendation  provides  that  all  appropriation  bills  be  care- 
fully considered  by  the  full  Appropriations  Committees  of  both  chambers. 
In  general,  committee  and  subcommittee  hearings  are  to  be  held  in  public 
session.  Printed  hearings  and  reports  on  appropriation  bills  would  have 
to  be  laid  before  each  chamber  at  least  three  legislative  days  before  their 
consideration  on  the  floor.  Hearings  should  be  based  on  a  uniform  appro- 
priation classification.  Each  appropriation  subcommittee  is  to  have  at  its 
disposal  four  qualified  staff  assistants  to  serve  both  majority  and  minority 
members,  and  the  committee  staff  is  to  be  supplied  with  modern  accounting 
machinery  and  equipment. 

The  third  recommendation  directs  the  Comptroller  General  to  submit 
annually  a  "general  service  audit"  of  each  federal  agency.  This  would  apply 
also  to  government  corporations.  The  service  audit  is  to  furnish  Congress 
with  information  on  the  general  financial  operation  of  the  agency  or  cor- 
poration and  its  care  in  handling  public  funds. 

The  fourth  recommendation  lays  clown  the  rule  that  all  appropriations  be 
in  definite  amounts.  The  custom  of  reappropriating  unexpended  balances  is 
to  be  discontinued,  except  for  public  works  carried  out  over  longer  periods. 
Transfer  of  funds  between  federal  agencies  is  to  cease.  All  "regular"  agen- 
cies are  to  follow  a  uniform  practice  of  returning  income  from  sales  or 
services  to  the  Treasury  Department. 

The  fifth  and  last  recommendation  aims  to  abolish  the  usage  of  attach- 
ing substantive  legislation  to  appropriation  bills.  Congressional  rules  should 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  619 

be  tightened  to  prevent  amendments  offered  as  "economy  limitations"  which 
actually  propose  legislative  changes.  The  Comptroller  General  is  to  survey 
limitations  on  appropriation  bills  to  identify  those  which  require  more 
money  to  carry  out  than  they  save.  Both  Appropriations  Committees  are  re- 
quested to  study  ways  and  means  of  limiting  any  increase  in  permanent 
appropriations. 

The  implications  of  these  proposals  for  the  budget  process  have  been 
indicated  in  a  preceding  section.09  Here  we  can  confine  ourselves  to  sug- 
gesting the  possibilities  of  sounder  fiscal  control  that  open  up  in  the  perspec- 
tive of  the  two  recommendations  in  which  the  Joint  Commitee  on  the 
Organization  of  Congress  has  attempted  to  redefine  parts  of  the  Comp- 
troller General's  mandate.  Both  proposals  are  relevant  not  only  from  the 
angle  of  their  specific  content  but  also  as  expressions  of  a  desire  for  a  re- 
orientation  in  the  outlook  of  the  General  Accounting  Office. 

The  committee  declared  that  the  General  Accounting  Office  has  "un- 
doubtedly served  a  valued  purpose  in  carefully  checking  all  government 
expenditures  to  see  that  they  come  within  the  law  and  that  amounts  claimed 
are  due."70  This  work  is  to  go  on.  In  addition,  however,  the  Comptroller 
General  should  present  to  the  legislature  "service  audits"  that  would 
"include  reports  on  the  administrative  performance  and  broad  operations 
of  the  agency,  together  with  information  that  will  enable  Congress  to 
determine  whether  public  funds  are  being  carelessly,  extravagantly,  or 
loosely  administered  and  spent."71  This  kind  of  audit — the  committee  makes 
plain — would  have  to  be  different  from  "the  present  detailed  audit  of  items" 
that  "does  not  reveal  the  general  condition  of  the  agency's  operation."72 

We  may  conjecture  that  true  service  audits  adjudging  "the  administrative 
performance  and  broad  operations"  of  an  agency  or  government  corporation 
could  be  attempted  only  upon  substantial  increases  in  the  staff  of  the  Comp- 
troller General.  In  fact,  staff  needs  for  this  purpose  are  quite  different  in 
character  from  those  hitherto  met  in  his  recruitment  policy.  The  kind  of 
staff  that  would  have  to  be  built  up  in  the  General  Accounting  Office  has 
in  the  past  rather  found  its  place  in  high-grade  departmental  management 
offices  or  in  the  Administrative  Management  Division  of  the  Bureau  of  the 
Budget.  Much  of  the  work  of  the  Administrative  Management  Division, 
indeed,  has  tended  to  come  close  to  the  purposes  of  the  service  audits  en- 
visaged by  the  committee.  We  could  imagine  a  fruitful  collaboration  in  this 
area  between  the  General  Accounting  Office  and  the  Bureau  of  the  Budget. 
Such  arrangement  would  at  the  same  time  prevent  unnecessary  duplication 
of  effort — a  duplication  which  literal  execution  of  the  committee  proposal 
would  make  inevitable. 


69  See  above  sec.  2,  "Justification." 

70  Op.  cit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  22. 

71  Ibid. 


620  FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY 

Unfortunately,  the  proposals  of  the  Joint  Committee  on  the  Organization 
of  Congress  stress  the  Comptroller  General's  audit  functions  without  simul- 
taneously taking  him  correspondingly  out  of  the  administrative  process. 
His  settlement  duties,  as  we  noted,  are  not  to  be  modified  or  shifted  to  an- 
other place  in  the  pattern  of  fiscal  control.  These  duties  alone  represent  a 
business  of  enormous  proportions.  The  Comptroller  General's  annual  'report 
for  1945  recorded  a  backlog  of  487,532,636  checks  in  unreconciled  depository 
accounts,  as  against  224,658,308  at  the  beginning  of  the  fiscal  year;  accounts 
containing  153,286,172  checks  were  reconciled,  while  416,160,500  paid  checks 
were  received.73  When  we  consider  the  volume  of  such  transactions^  should 
become  clear  that  heavier  accent  on  activities  more  closely  related  to  auditing 
may  in  the  end  merely  produce  intensified  conflict  of  purposes  in  the 
operations  of  the  General  Accounting  Office.  Moreover,  the  proposals  do 
not  bring  significantly  nearer  any  real  working  integration  of  the  audit 
function  with  the  exercise  of  congressional  oversight  and  control;  for  this 
purpose  a  mechanism  such  as  a  legislative  committee  on  public  accounts 
to  whom  the  Comptroller  General  could  regularly  report  is  indispensable. 

Looking  at  the  "administrative  performance"  of  an  agency  in  its  entirety 
would  be  a  new  experience  for  the  General  Accounting  Office.  Shift  of 
attention  in  this  direction  may  be  an  important  step  toward  effective  general 
auditing  and  comprehensive  reporting  to  Congress.  The  same  impulse  may 
be  generated  in  the  other  assignment  that  the  committee  has  in  mind  for  the 
Comptroller  General.  Scrutiny  of  limitations  on  appropriation  bills  to 
determine  those  which  appear  to  entail  disproportionate  cost  is  likely  to  be 
an  antidote  to  his  traditional  preoccupation  with  the  enforcement  of  limita- 
tions. The  very  admission  of  the  committee  that  so-called  economy  limita- 
tions may  be  "extravagant"74  is  a  highly  suggestive  gesture.  Many  of  the 
economy  limitations  have  accomplished  little,  but  pose  exasperating  problems 
to  those  responsible  for  sound  administrative  management. 

The  immediate  fate  of  the  specific  fiscal  proposals  of  the  joint  committee 
is  of  less  importance  for  our  purposes  than  their  significance  as  indications 
of  a  trend.  The  necessary  compromises  with  the  legislative  expediencies 
of  the  moment,,  and  the  uncertainties  attending  any  predictions  as  to  how 
a  charter  of  new  institutional  arrangements  will  work  out  in  practice,  com- 
bine to  postpone  final  judgments.  It  is  plain  that  neither  the  joint  com- 
mittee nor  its  parent  Congress  was  in  a  mood  for  revolutionary  departures; 
and  equally  plain  that  the  separation  of  powers  sharply  limits  the  range  of 
available  innovations.  But  the  evident  concern  for  practical  improvements 
in  financial  accountability  is  a  wholesome  sign  in  a  government  that  has 
grown  to  new  stature  and  assumed  a  scale  of  public  responsibilities  only 
dimly  foreshadowed  when  the  Budget  and  Accounting  Act  was  passed 

7*  Washington,  1946,  p.  26. 

74  Op.  tit.  above  in  note  4,  p.  23. 


FISCAL  ACCOUNTABILITY  621 

The  Legislative  Reorganization  Act  of  1946  was  passed  in  the  shadow 
of  impending  congressional  elections  and  in  the  rush  of  adjournment  to  the 
first  long  vacation  the  members  of  Congress  have  granted  themselves  for 
several  years.  The  act  carried  through  in  modified  form  a  good  share  of 
the  joint  committee's  fiscal  recommendations.  It  sanctioned  the  requirement 
that  the  legislative  branch,  by  concurrent  resolution,  annually  determine  an 
over-all  limit  on  appropriations  for  the  year,  and  express  the  sense  of 
Congress  that  the  public  debt  should  be  increased  if  this  amount  exceeds 
anticipated  receipts.  The  harsh  method  of  policing  legislative  budget  ceil- 
ings— uniform  percentage  cuts  if  actual  appropriations  should  run  higher 
than  the  fixed  total — was  eliminated,  however,  and  no  substitute  for  it  was 
agreed  upon.  Passage  of  the  concurrent  resolution,  and  its  effect  if  passed, 
remained  in  the  discretion  of  Congress  in  each  succeeding  fiscal  year. 

Practically  all  features  of  the  second,  fourth  and  fifth  recommendations  of 
the  joint  committee,  outlined  above,  were  adopted.  In  place  of  the  annual 
"general  service  audit"  contemplated  in  the  third  proposal,  the  Comptroller 
General  was  directed  from  time  to  time  to  make  an  "expenditure  analysis" 
of  each  federal  agency  such  as  will,  in  his  opinion,  "enable  Congress  to  de- 
termine whether  public  funds  have  been  economically  and  efficiently  admin- 
istered and  expended."  Moreover,  the  reorganized  Committee  on  Expend- 
itures in  the  Executive  Departments  in  each  house  was  specifically  assigned 
the  duty  of  "receiving  and  examining  reports  of  the  Comptroller  General" 
and  of  making  recommendations  on  their  subject  matter.  It  is  easy  to  sec 
that  the  administration  of  these  provisions  leaves  wide  latitude  for  energy 
and  discretion. 

The  emphasis  upon  a  redirection  of  the  audit  function  away  from  the 
detail  and  toward  the  general  may  prove  a  lasting  contribution.  Full 
accountability  for  the  level  of  efficiency  throughout  the  executive  branch  is 
woven  into  the  tenets  of  representative  government.  The  more  closely  we 
approximate  a  satisfactory  solution  of  this  problem,  the  less  ground  will 
there  be  for  the  ill-considered  contention  that  inefficiency  is  the  price  of 
democracy. 


•  * MM  KM  K *  K X X X  X X X  X X  X  ********************************** ** 


Index 


Accountability,  administrative,  105,  114,  339 
ff.t  512  ff.f  577  ff.,  fiscal;  23,  339  ff., 
577  ff.;  popular,  57,  339  ff. 

Accounting,  see  Accountability,  fiscal 

Accuracy,  of  budget,  sec  Budgeting,  prin- 
ciples 

Adams,  Henry,  28 

Adams,  John,  21,  161 

Adams,  John  Quincy,  21 

Adjudication,  administrative,  519  ff.;  sec  also 
Independent  regulatory  agencies;  Judicial 
review 

Adjutant  General's  Office,  564 

Administration,  college,  5,  160  ff.;  eccles- 
iastic, 5;  judicial,  5,  7;  see  also  Attorney 
General;  Justice,  Department  of;  military, 
5,  52,  483,  521  ff.;  see  also  War  Depart- 
ment 

Administration,  public,  administrative  sur- 
veys, 472  ff.;  art  or  science,  4,  48  ff.; 
as  fitting  process,  108;  business  manager, 
160  ff.;  characteristics,  3  ff.,  6,  27,  38  ff., 
106  ff.;  definition,  3  ff.;  elements,  6  ff.;  his- 
tory, 9  ff.-,  improvement,  448  ff.,  462  ff.; 
nomenclature,  7  ff.;  scope,  5  ff.;  self -analy- 
sis 34  ff.;  social  function,  98  ff.;  spirit,  69 
ff.;  see  also  Ideology,  administrative;  study, 
27  ff.;  theory  and  practice,  50;  training, 
37  ff.t  544  ff.;  see  also  Democratic  admin- 
istration; Management 

Administrative  class,  see  Administration,  pub- 
lic, training;  Democratic  administration; 
Personnel  administration,  public;  President's 
Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improvement 

Administrative  law,   see  Judicial   review 

Administrative  Procedure  Act,  218  n.  6,  220, 
232,  235,  387,  391,  529  ff. 

Administrative  Research,  Bureau  of,  Los  An- 
geles, 459 

Agricultural  Economics,  Bureau  of,  130,  201, 
289 

Agricultural  Society,  16 

Agriculture,  Department  of,  15  ff.,  44,  79, 
130,  186,  201,  204,  217,  222  ff.,  261,  267 
ff.,  277,  285  ff.,  290  ff.,  319  ff.,  345  ff.. 
391  ff.,  454  ff.,  524  ff.,  532,  551  ff.,  572, 
585;  Graduate  School,  40,  572;  Yearbook,  80 


Agriculture,   organized,    see   Interest   groups, 

Agriculture,  Department  of 
Alabama,  University  of,  450  ff. 
Aldndge,  John  A.,  475 
Alien  Registration  Act,  342 

Allegiance,  administrative,  see  Ideology,  ad- 
ministrative; Morale;  Organization,  informal 

Allsetter,  W.  R.,  cited,  154  ff. 

American,  Bar  Association,  63,  232,  315, 
527  ff.,  541  ff.;  Federation  of  Government 
Employees,  576;  Federation  of  Labor,  327, 
575  ff.;  see  also  Interest  groups;  Institute 
of  Public  Opinion,  79;  Management  Asso- 
ciation, cited,  154  ff.;  Medical  Associa- 
tion, 370;  see  also  Interest  groups;  Mu- 
nicipal Association,  83,  172,  450;  Public 
Health  Association,  450;  Public  Welfare 
Association,  450;  Public  Works  Associa- 
tion 450;  Society  for  Municipal  Improve- 
ments, 450;  Society  of  Mechanical  Engi- 
neers, 451;  Statistical  Association,  370; 
Telephone  &  Telegraph  Company,  239; 
University,  40  ff. 

Analysis,  administrative,  see  Organization; 
Administration,  public,  improvement;  Sur- 
veys, administrative;  Procedure,  adminis- 
trative 

Anonymity,  official,  68  ff. 

Anti-Saloon   League,  see  Interest  groups 

Antitrust  Division,  580 

Appeals  board,  for  grievances,  see  Personnel 
administration,  public,  gnevances 

Appleby,  Paul   H.,  cited,  203  ff.,  495 

Appointment,  see  Chief  executive,  legal  pow- 
ers; Personnel  administration,  public 

Apprenticeship,  administrative,  40 

Appropriations,  see  Budgeting;  Committees, 
see  Budgeting 

Aristotle,  56 

Arlidge  case,  535 

Army,  Corps  of  Engineers,  249,  289  ff.t  345: 
Service  Forces,  148,  419,  460 

Arnall,  Go\crnor,   168 

"Assistant  President,"  see  Coordination,  inter- 
departmental 

Assistants,  administrative,  to  the  President, 
23,  178  ff.;  departmental,  201  ff. 

Association  of  American  Railroads,  85,  369 

Atlanta,  285 


623 


624 


INDEX 


Attorney  General,  189,  228,  252,  342,  530, 
612 

Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Procedure,  218  ».  6,  232,  390  n.  5, 
526,  528  ff.;  cited,  234  ff.,  522;  proposals, 
219  ff.,  539  ff. 

Auditing,  606  ff.i  administrative  checks,  609 
ff.l  and  operating  responsibility,  615  ff.; 
and  settlement,  614;  beginnings,  607  ff.; 
in  England,  606  ff.;  of  performance,  618 
ff.,  621;  versus  control,  613 

Authoritarianism,  sec  Morale 

Authority,  and  leadership,  see  Chief  execu- 
tive, leadership;  administrative,  see  Democ- 
racy, office;  Judicial  review;  Morale;  Or- 
ganization, informal 

Automatism,  social,  and  responsibility,  506 

Auxiliary  services,  see  Organization,  staff; 
Staff  agencies 

B 

Bagchot,  Walter,  cited,  161,  381 

Baldwin,  Stanley,  64 

Ballinger-Pinchot    controversy,    144 

Banks,  tee  Federal  Land  Banks;  Reconstruc- 
tion Finance  Corporation 

Barnard,  Chester  I.,  46 

Baruch,  Bernard,  cited,  98,  128 

Beard,  Charles  A.,  50,  450  ff.;  cited  315 

Benjamin,  Robert  M.,  529  ff.,  540 

Bentham,  Jeremy,  115 

Benton,  William,  199 

Beveridge,  William  H.,  588 

Bevin,  Ernest,  337  ff. 

Biography,  of  administrators,  see  Administra- 
tion, public,  study 

Bipartisan  boards,  see  Independent  regulatory 
agencies;  Interest  groups 

Bituminous   Coal    Commission,    465 

Blachly,  Frederick  F.,  cited,  63 

Blandford,  John  B.,  cited,  366  n.  2 

Board  of  Investigation  and  Research,  citeo*» 
229  ff.t  235 

Boards,  see  Independent  regulatory  agencies; 
administrative,  see  Interest  groups,  represen- 
tation; *  bipartisan,  see  Interest  groups,  rep- 
resentation; combined,  see  Combined  boards; 
tripartite,  see  Interest  groups,  representation 

Bonneville,  291 

Boston,  159,  185,  285  ff. 

Bowron,  Mayor,  545 

"Brain  trust,"  195 

Brandeis,  Justice,  116 

Brandenburg,  265 

Brecht,  Arnold,  cited,  205 

Bridgeman  Committee,  cited,  279 

Brooking*  Institution,  33  ff.,  449  ff.,  465; 
cited,  187  ff. 


Brookline,  Mass.,  465 

Brooks,  George,  327 

Brown,  J.  Douglas,  327 

Brownlow,  Louis,  23  n.  15,  178 

Bryce,  James,  30 

Buchanan,  President,  167 

Budget  and  Accounting  Act,  23,  32,  177  ff., 
192,  579  ff.f  583  ff.,  606,  609,  612 

Budget  and  Efficiency,  Bureau  of,  Los  An- 
geles, 459 

Budget  Bureau,  35,  177  ff.,  191  ff.,  244  ff., 
286  ff.,  370  ff.,  432  ff.,  454  ff.,  578  ff. 

Budgeting,  23  ff.,  32,  35,  174,  177  ff.,  192 
ff.,  205,  577  ff.-t  allotments,  603  ff.;  and 
personnel  administration,  549  ff.;  appor- 
tionments, 604  ff.;  appropriations,  580  ff., 
618;  as  staff  activity,  147;  budget  ceilings, 
618;  budget  review,  600  n.  37;  by  projects, 
585;  capital,  see  Capital  budget;  Planning, 
techniques;  coordination,  593  ff.;  deficien- 
cies, 580  ff.;  departmental,  594  ff.;  execu- 
tive budget,  586  ff.;  execution,  598  ff.;  ex- 
traordinary budget,  599  ff.;  fund  control, 
603;  fund  transfers,  592  ff.,  618;  justifica- 
tions, 582  ff.,  618;  legislative  ceilings,  590 
ff.,  621;  legislative  procedure,  587  ff.;  ordi- 
nary budget,  599  ff.;  personnel  ceilings,  605 
ff.;  principles,  598  ff.,  608  ff.;  reporting, 
605;  see  also  General  staff,  administrative; 
Government  corporations;  Staff  agencies; 
Legislative  control 

Bureaucracy,  51  ff.,  80,  93  ff.,  98  ff.,  414  ff.; 
see  also  Interest  groups;  Organization,  in- 
formal ;  Procedure,  administrative 

Burke,  Edmund,  cited,  527 

Burnham,  James,  cited,  72 

Bush,  Vannevar,  81 

Business,  administration,  see  Management, 
private;  and  government,  11  ff.;  see  also 
Service  state;  organized,  see  Interest  groups; 
manager,  in  administration,  see  Adminis- 
tration, public,  business  manager;  practice, 
and  responsibility,  504  ff. 

Byrd,  Senator,  449;  cited,  257 


Cabinet,  coordinativc  role,  195  ff.;  government, 
see  England;  informal,  307  ff.;  potentiali- 
ties of,  182  ff.;  see  also  Planning 

Cairo,  University  of,  5 

California,   159;  University  of,  454,  569 

Call,  for  estimates,  see  Budgeting,  justifica- 
tions 

Capital  budget,  600;  see  also  Planning,  tech- 
niques 

Car  pool,  312 

Career  service,  influence  of,  204  ff.;  see  also 
Ideology,  administrative;  Personnel  admin- 
istration, public 


INDEX 


625 


Carnegie,  Andrew,  168 

Catholic,  Church,  see  Administration,  eccles- 
iastic; Welfare  Conference,  National,  see 
Interest  groups 

Census  Bureau,  370 

Central,  Electricity  Board,  331;  Statistical 
Board,  196 

Chambers  of  Commerce,  see  Interest  groups 

Charts,  see  Organization;  Surveys,  adminis- 
trative; Work  simplification 

Chatficld,  Helen  L.,  cited,  420 

Chicago,  159,  285  ff.,  553,  572;  University 
of,  450,  569 

On^exscjiiiXS*  10,  36,  53  ff.,  72  ff.,  158  ff.; 
and  foreign  policy,  171  ff.;  and  govern- 
ment corporations,  236  ff.;  and  independent 
regulatory  agencies,  223  ff.;  and  interest 
groups,  172  ff.',  and  legislative  control,  339 
ff.;  and  reorganization,  176  ff.;  see  also 
Reorganization;  and  teamwork,  514  ff.; 
business  leaders,  168  ff.;  executive  direc- 
tion, 174  ff.;  external  relationships,  169 
ff.;  leadership,  7  ff.,  162  ff.;  legal  powers, 
101,  162  ff.,  175  ff.,  354  ff.;  municipal,  158 
ff.;  personal  qualifications,  162  ff.;  private 
management,  159  ff.;  responsibility,  512 
ff.;  state,  158  ff.;  see  also  Budgeting;  Plan- 
ning 

Children's  Bureau,  17,  142,  318  ff.,  370 

Christian  thought,  and  responsibility,  sec  Re- 
sponsibility, essentials 

Churches,  Federal  Council  of,  tee  Interest 
groups 

Churchill,  Winston,  338 

Cincinnati,  18  ff.;  University  of,  40,  569 

City-manager  plan,  7,  24,  73  ff.,  160,  187 

Civil  Aeronautics,  Administration,  86,  465, 
524  ff.;  Board,  221 

Civil  servants,  rights,  92,  491  ff.;  see  also 
Personnel  administration,  public 

Civil  Service,  Assembly,  450,  466;  Commis- 
sion, see  Personnel  administration,  public 

Clarity,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting,  principles 

Class  theory,  see  Interest  groups 

Classification,  tee  Personnel  administration, 
public;  Act,  23,  32,  551,  553,  581 

Clay,  Henry,  86;  cited,  609 

Clearance,  legislative,  586;  of  appointments, 
356  ff.;  of  policy  proposals,  370  ff.;  sta- 
tistical, 586;  tee  also  Budget  Bureau;  Co- 
ordination 

Cleveland,  285 

Cleveland,  Frederick  A.,  32 

Cleveland,  President,  23,   167;  cited,  15 

Clientele  agencies,  15  ff.,  222  ff.,  304  ff., 
318  ff. 

Clubs,  employee,  312  ff.;  USDA,  286  ff. 

Coast  Guard,  United  States,  524  ff. 


College    administration,    tee    Administration, 

college 

Columbia  University,  30,  450 
Combined  boards,  wartime,   192  ff. 
Command,   dual,   see  Supervision;   unity   of, 

see  Organization 
Commerce,  Department  of,   15  ff.,  113,   186, 

189,222,  319  ff.,  356,  459 
Commercial  Company,  United  States,  18,  243 

Commission,  of  Inquiry  on  Public  Service 
Personnel,  23,  41,  450;  on  Economy  and 
Efficiency,  23,  32,  449;  on  Law  Observance 
and  Enforcement,  National,  126  ff.;  on 
Rectification  of  Salaries,  Congressional,  32; 
plan,  of  city  government,  24 

Commissions,  of  inquiry,  80  ff.;  see  also  In- 
dependent regulatory  agencies 

Committee,  for  Congested  Areas,  289;  on  Eco- 
nomic Security,  126;  on  Machinery  of 
Government,  115;  on  Non -Essential  Ex- 
penditures, Congressional,  259;  on  the  Or- 
ganization of  Congress,  Joint,  589  ff.;  pro- 
posals, 617  ff.;  see  also  Legislative  control, 
reform;  on  Public  Administration,  450;  on 
the  Reorganization  of  the  Administrative 
Branch,  Congressional,  190;  on  Taxation 
and  Retrenchment,  New  York,  449;  on 
Trade  Agreements,  197 

Committees,  advisory,  79;  area  production 
urgency,  289,  327  ff.;  Cabinet,  182  ff.; 
hearings,  see  Budgeting,  executive  budget; 
interbureau,  205  ff.;  interdepartmental,  196 
ff.;  legislative,  meeting  with  administrators, 
360;  manpower  priorities,  289;  use  of,  in 
administrative  improvement,  454  ff. 

Commodity    Credit   Corporation,    242,   255 

Commons,  John  R.,  30 

Communication,  administrative,  see  Surveys, 
administrative;  and  field  organization,  280 
ff.;  and  middle  management,  408  ff. 

Community  analysis,  292  ff. 

Comparative    study,   administrative,    48 

Compensation,  tee  Personnel  administration, 
public 

Competitive  bidding,  252 

Comprehensiveness,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting, 
principles 

Comptroller  General,  179  ff.,  238  ff.t  244 
ff.f  389,  455,  582  ff.;  see  also  Auditing; 
Government  corporations 

Confederation,  Articles  of,  99 

Conference  of  Mayors,  United  States,  83,  172 

Congress  of  Industrial  Organizations,  327  ff., 
575  ff.;  tee  alto  Interest  groups 

Connally,  Senator,  cited,  352 

Connecticut,  549 

Consultants,  outside,  453  ff. 


626 


INDEX 


Consultation,  administrative,  307  ff.;  tec  also 
Independent  regulatory  agencies;  Interest 
groups;  and  coordination,  595  ff. 

Consumers'  associations,  see  Interest  groups 

Contract  Settlement  Act,  616 

Contracts,  government,  see  Purchasing,  gov- 
ernmental 

Control,  agencies,  see  Staff  agencies;  of  op- 
erations, see  Management,  middle;  see  also 
Chief  executive;  Legislative  control 

Cooley,  Judge,  216  n.  5 

Coolidge,  President,  167,  225 

Cooperatives,  Central  Bank  for,  250;  regional 
banks  for,  250;  see  also  Interest  groups 

Coordinating  Service,  286  ff.;  see  also  Com- 
mittees, interdepartmental 

Coordination,  and  field  organization,  284  ff.; 
and  organization,  152  ff.;  budgetary,  593 
ff.;  effect  of  reorganizations  on,  20;  gov- 
ernment-wide, 35  ff.;  see  also  Budget  Bu- 
reau; interdepartmental,  191  ff.;  of  legis- 
lative proposals,  192  ff.;  of  policy,  182,  228 
ff.;  of  statistical  activities,  192  ff.;  regional, 
287  ff.;  resistance  to,  see  Organization,  po- 
litical factors;  see  also  Budgeting;  Budget 
Bureau;  Chief  executive;  Clearance 

Corporations,  governmental,  see  Government 
corporations 

Corruption,  31,  448  ff. 

Corwin,  Edward  S.,  cited,   176 

Cost  accounting,  see  Accountability,  fiscal; 
Work  measurement 

Cost  of  living,  see  Personnel  administration, 
public,  compensation 

Council,  of  Economic  Advisers,  177,  179, 
181,  588;  of  Ministers,  see  Russia;  of  Per- 
sonnel Administration,  41  n.  33,  370,  551; 
of  State  Governments,  24,  83,  172,  450 

County  government,  see  Government,  county 

Court  of  Claims,  539 

Courts,   see   Judicial    review;    Supreme   Court 

Cushman,  Robert  E.,  cited,  222,  231,  541 

Customs,  Bureau  of,  525 


Dallas,  285  ff. 

Darwin,  506 

Davenport,  Frederick,  449 

Davies,  Ralph,  324 

Debt,    public,    see   Accountability,   fiscal 

Decentralization,  12  ff.,  149  ff.;  see  also 
Field  organization 

Deconcentration,    see   Decentralization 

Defense,  Department  of,  180;  Homes  Cor- 
poration, 242  ff.;  Housing  Coordination, 
Division  of,  152;  Plant  Corporation,  243, 
261;  Supplies  Corporation,  243,  261 

Deficiencies,  see  Budgeting,  deficiencies 


Delegation,  54,  75  ff.;  see  also  Chief  execu- 
tive; Departmental  system;  Management, 
middle 

Democracy,  office,  69  ff.,  91  ff. 

Democratic  administration,  69  ff.,  72  ff.,  437 
ff.;  and  morale,  481  ff.;  see  also  Personnel 
administration,  public,  employee  relations 

Democratic  theory,  306  ff. 

Denver,  285  ff. 

Departmental  system,  184  ff.;  bureau  pattern, 
202  ff.,  346  ff.;  business  examples,  185; 
executive  function,  200  ff.;  growth,  16  ff.; 
nomenclature,  198;  resistance  to  direction, 
202  ff.;  secretarial  level,  198  ff.;  see  also 
Administration,  public,  improvement; 
Budgeting;  Management,  middle;  Person- 
nel administration,  public;  Responsibility, 
administrative 

Despotism,  see  Bureaucracy 

Detroit,  18  ff.,  159 

Dcwcy,  Governor,  75,  165 

Dhonau,  May  L.,  cited,  271 

Dicey,  A.  V.,  cited,  537  ff. 

Dickinson,  John,  cited,  100 

Dictatorship,  see  Bureaucracy 

Dimock,  Marshall  E.,  241  n.  4 

Disaster  Loan  Corporation,  243 

Disbursement  Division,  286,  272 

Disbursing  officer,  see  Accountability,  fiscal 

Discipline,  administrative,  478  ff.;  and  civic 
rights,  493 

Discretion,  administrative,  see  Independent 
regulatory  agencies;  Bureaucracy;  Policy, 
administrative,  formulation;  "Rule  of  Law" 

Districts,  see  Governmental  districts 

Dockery  Act,  612 

Domestic  Commerce,  80 

Donoughmore  Committee,  64 

Draft,  see  Selective  Service  System 

Due  process  of  law,  10  ff.;  see  also  Judicial 
review 

Duguit,  Leon,  538 


Eastman,  Joseph  B.,  209  n.  2 

Eaton,  Dot  man  B.,  28 

Economic  Stabilization  Act,  333  ff. 

Economic  warfare,  see  Commercial  Company, 
United  States 

Economy,  in  government,  see  Budgeting; 
Procedure,  administrative;  mixed,  26,  65 
ff.f  87  ff.,  98  ff.;  see  also  Service  state 

Education,  see  Interest  groups;  School  dis- 
tricts 

Efficiency,  Bureau  of,  23;  see  also  Procedure, 
administrative;  Administration,  public; 
Budget  Bureau 

Einstein,  Albert,  528 

Eisenhower,  General,  164 


INDEX 


627 


Elective  office,  186  ff.;  tradition,  11,  20  ff. 

Electoral  College,  91 

Electric  Home  and  Farm  Authority,  248,  255 

tlite,  historic  role,  21 

Ely,  Richard  T.,  30 

Emergencies,  impact  on  administration,  25 

Emergency,  Council,  National,  287  ff.;  Fleet 
Corporation,  241,  616;  Price  Control  Act, 
536  n.  25 

Employee,  rating,  sec  Personnel  administra- 
tion, public,  rating;  suggestion  systems,  see 
Supervision,  administrative,  and  employee 
initiative 

Employment,  Act,  177,  179,  181,  588;  high- 
level,  15,  26,  101  ff.,  197  ff.;  public,  tee 
Personnel  administration,  public,  employ- 
ment; Service,  United  States,  87 

England,  52  ff.,  58,  63  ff.,  76  ff.,  92  ff.,  101, 
115,  161,  186,  195  ff.,  205,  238,  266  ff., 
279,  312  ff.,  331  ff.,  337  ff.,  343  ff.,  359, 
451,  508,  523,  529,  535  ff..  558,  564,  575, 
601,  606  ff.,  614;  civil  service  recruitment, 
39  ff.;  influence  on  American  administra- 
tion, 9  ff. 

Equality,  10  ff.;  procedural  safeguards,  385  ff. 

Estimates,   see   Budgeting,    justifications 

Ethics,  administrative,  see  Ideology,  adminis- 
trative; of  administrative  counsel,  70 

Examinations,  see  Personnel  administration, 
public 

Executive,  see  Chief  executive;  budget,  see 
Budgeting 

Executive-legislative  relations,  see  Legislative 
control;  Policy 

Executive  Office  of  the  President,  23,  35  ff.f 
109,  153,  179  ff.,  191  ff.t  288,  292,  549, 
597 

Expenditures,  federal,  19  ff.;  see  also  Budget- 
ing; Accountability,  fiscal 

Experience,  evaluation  of,  see  Personnel  ad- 
ministration, public,  tests 

Experts,  functional,  see  Field  organization, 
field-headquarters  relations;  use  of  outside, 
32  ff.,  453  ff. 

Export-Import  Bank,  247,  255 

Extraordinary  budget,  see  Budgeting 


Farm,  Bureau  Federation,  see  Interest  groups; 
credit,  see  Federal  Land  Banks;  Credit 
Administration,  243  ff.,  261,  459;  Loan 
Act,  243;  Security  Administration,  84 

Farmers  Union,  National,  355 

Fascism,   481;  see  also  Hidcr;  Mussolini 

Fayol,  Henri,  46 

Federal,  Barge  Lines,  241,  247;  Bureau  of 
Investigation,  see  Investigations;  business 
associations,  286;  Communications  Corn- 


Federal — ( Continued) 

mission,  20,  61,  221  ff.,  522;  Deposit  In- 
surance Corporation,  242,  246,  255,  260 
ff.t  524  ff.;  Employment  Stabilization  Board, 
126;  Farm  Mortgage  Corporation,  242,  247 
ff.;  government,  see  Government,  federal; 
Home  Loan  Bank  Board,  152  ff.,  522  #,/ 
Home  Loan  Bank  Review,  80;  Home  Loan 
Banks,  242,  250;  Housing  Administration, 
153;  Housing  Authority,  152;  Intermediate 
Credit  Banks,  243;  Land  Banks,  241  ff., 
249  n.  17,  250,  261;  Loan  Agency,  152 
ff.,  190;  Power  Commission,  20,  221  ff., 
289  ff.;  Prison  Industries,  242,  253  ff.t  261; 
Public  Housing  Authority,  153;  Reserve 
Bulletin,  80;  Reserve  System,  20,  211,  221, 
318  ff.,  522  ff.;  Savings  and  Loan  Insur- 
ance Corporation,  242,  247  ff.;  Security 
Agency,  145,  190,  222,  277,  391  ff.,  522; 
Surplus  Commodities  Corporation,  242; 
Trade  Commission,  20,  61,  221  ff.,  224  ff.t 
390;  Works  Agency,  152  ff..  190,  see  also 
National 

Federalism,   12   ff.;  cooperative,  25,  81   ff. 

Federalists,  21 

Field  organization,  144,  264  ff.;  centraliza- 
tion, 269  ff.;  communication,  280  ff.;  coor- 
dination, 284  ff.;  decentralization,  269  ff.; 
dual  command,  277  ft.',  field-headquarters 
relationships,  277  ff.;  growth,  264  ff.; 
joint  planning,  289  #.;  state,  268  #.;  tech- 
nological factors,  267  ff.;  see  also  Organiza- 
tion 

Fiscal,  accountability,  see  Accountability,  fiscal; 
policy,  see  Policy,  fiscal;  programs,  formu- 
lation, 586;  see  also  Budget  Bureau 

Fish  and  Wildlife  Service,  290 

Fish,  Lounsbury  S.,  cited,  122 

Flow  chart,  see  Surveys,  administrative 

Follett,  Mary  P.,  44  ff.,  437  ff.;  cited,  176, 
514 

Food  and  Drug  Administration,  222 

Foreign,  and  Domestic  Commerce,  Bureau 
of,  17,  370,  596;  policy,  and  State  De- 
partment, 194;  policy,  Executive  Com- 
mittee for  Economic,  197;  see  also  Chief 
executive,  and  foreign  policy 

Forest  Service,  United  States,  137,  144,  147 
ff.,  289,  291  ff. 

Four  Years  Law,  21 

France,  52,  63  ff..  184,  264  ff.t  283,  343 
359,  451,  538  ff. 

Frank,  Jerome,  cited,  529 

Frederick  William,  Great  Elector,  265 

Freedom  of  expression,  administrative,  111; 
see  also  Ideology,  administrative 

Freight  rates,  southern  and  western,  228  ff. 

Freud,  Sigmund,  528 

Freund,  Ernst,  cited,  106 


628 


INDEX 


Friedrich,  Carl  J.,  cited,  55 

Frontier,  influence  on  administration,  II  ff. 


Gallatin,  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  609 

Gallup  polls,  79 

Gang-process  chart,  sec  Surveys,  training 

Gantt,  Henry  L.,  452 

Gaus,  John  M.,  44 

Gellhorn,  Waiter,  529 

General  Accounting  Office,  history,  613;  see 
also  Comptroller  General 

General  Electric  Company,  122 

General  Motors  Corporation,  55 

General  staff,  administrative,  456  ff.;  Army, 
see  Planning 

Geological  Survey,  603 

George,  Senator,  cited,  356 

Georgc-Decn  Act,  40 

George  Washington  University,  40  ff. 

Georgia,  228 

Germany,  52,  53,  205,  316,  451,  494,  502, 
538  ff. 

Gifford,  Walter  S.,  168 

Gilbreth,  Frank  B.,  452,  466 

Gobbledygook,  68  ff. 

Godkin,  E.  L.,  28 

Golden,  Clinton  S.,  327  ff. 

Good  Neighbor  policy,  243 

Goodnow,  Frank  J.,  30 

Government  corporations,  236  ff.;  administra- 
tive expenses,  247  ff.;  and  political  responsi- 
bility, 256  ff.;  budgetary  control,  250  ff.; 
Control  Act,  239  ff.,  593,  616  ff.;  growth, 
17  ff.,  240  ff.;  information,  259  ff.;  munici- 
pal utilities,  17  ff.;  overhead  control,  244  ff.; 
personnel  control,  255;  powers  of  Comp- 
troller General,  251  ff. 

Government,  county,  growth,  19;  federal, 
growth,  19  ff.;  limited,  11  ff.,  14  ff.;  local, 
administrative  reforms,  24,  beginnings,  9, 
English,  77,  see  also  Community  analysis, 
Intergovernmental  relations;  Manual,  United 
States,  287;  municipal,  administrative  im- 
provement, 27  ff.,  448  ff.;  "of  laws,"  57, 
544,  577;  personnel,  see  Personnel  admin- 
istration, public;  Printing  Office,  252;  state, 
administrative  improvement,  448  ff.,  growth, 
19;  sec  also  Intergovernmental  relations; 
Personnel  administration,  public 

Governmental   districts,   special-purpose,  9  ff. 

Governor,  see  Chief  executive 

Governors'  Conference,  172 

Graduate  School  of  the  Department  of  Agri- 
culture, 40,  572 

Graham,  George  A.,  38 

Grain  Corporation,  United  States,  241 

Grand  Coulee,  291 

Granger  Laws,  14 


Grant,  General,  167 

Great  Britain,  see  England 

Greek  Orthodox  Church,  see  Administration, 
ecclesiastic 

Green   sheets,   see    Budgeting,   justifications 

Grievances,  see  Personnel  administration,  pub- 
lic, grievances 

GrifTenhagen  and  associates,  33 

Group  participation,  see  Morale 

Gulick,  Luther,  23  n.  15 

H 

Haldanc  report,  115 

Hamilton,  Alexander,  100,  125,  166,  582, 
608;  influence  on  administration,  12  ff.,  15 

Hancock,  John,  128;  cited,  98 

Hanscn,  Alvin  H.,  588 

Harding,  President,   167,  224,  614 

Harvard  University,  5,  30,  450,  546  n.  4, 
569;  School  of  Business  Administration, 
441?. 

Hatch  Act,  493 

Hauriou,  cited,  283 

Hayek,  F.  A.,  cited,  72  ff. 

Headquarters,   see   Field   organization 

Hearing,  budget,  see  Budgeting,  justifications; 
legislative,  budget,  588  ff.t  618;  see  also 
Regulation,  governmental  Independent  reg- 
ulatory agencies;  Judicial  review 

Henderson,  Leon,  328  ff. 

Herring,  Pendlcton,  cited,  188 

Hetzcl,  Ralph,  327 

Hewart  of  Bury,  529;  cited,  59  ff. 

Hierarchy,  and  middle  management,  400  ff.; 
see  also  Legislative  control;  Organization 

Hill,  James  J.,  168 

Hillman,  Sidney,  327  ff. 

Hitler,  52  ff.,  125,  502 

Hoan,  Mayor,  169 

Holdcn,  Paul  E.,  cited,  122 

Holland,  52 

Holmes,  Justice,  cited,  18 

Home  Owners  Loan  Corporation,  242,  247 
ff.f  256,  258,  522  ff. 

Hoover,  Herbert,  103,  190,  225 

Hopkins,  Harry,  175,  308 

House,  Colonel,  175,  308 

Housing,  see  National  Housing  Agency;  Au- 
thority, United  States,  152  ff.,  289;  Cor- 
poration, United  States,  241 

Hughes,  Governor,  449 

Human  factor,  see  Morale 

Human  Nutrition  and  Home  Economks, 
Bureau  of,  391  ff. 

Humphrey   case,    151,    176,   210   ff.,  224   ff. 


INDEX 


629 


I 


Ideology,  administrative,  8  ff.,  36  ff.,  206, 544, 
558  0.  18;  and  administrative  policy,  373 
ff.;  and  administrative  procedure,  381  ff.; 
see  also  Interest  groups;  Organization,,  in- 
formal; Personnel  administration,  public, 
employee  relations 

Illinois,  192;  state  reorganization,  24;  state 
constitutional  convention,  32  ff. 

Immigration  and  Naturalization,  Bureau  of, 
525 

Incentives,  see  Morale 

Independent  regulatory  agencies,  23,  29  ff., 
151,  186  ff.,  207  ff.,  540  ff.;  and  legis- 
lative control,  348  ff.;  inertia,  228  ff.;  ju- 
dicial control,  217  ff.,  519  ff.;  proposals 
of  President's  Committee  on  Administrative 
Management,  234  ff.;  segregation  of  func- 
tions, 233  ff.,  537  ff.;  state,  62  n.  15,  226 
ff.;  status  guarantees,  207  ff.;  types  of,  207 
ff.;  see  also  Bureaucracy;  Regulation,  gov- 
ernmental 

Indoctrination,    see    Ideology,    administrative 

Influence,  see  Organization,   informal 

Information,  administrative,  80,  174  ff.;  and 
administrative  surveys,  467  ff.;  and  field 
organization,  281  ff.;  and  government  cor- 
porations, see  Government  corporattons,  in- 
formation; and  public  interest,  114  ff.;  re- 
porting schemes,  419  ff.;  see  also  Budget- 
ing, reporting 

Information,  public,  on  legislature,  353  ff. 

Inland  Waterways  Corporation,  241,  247,  253, 
259  ff..  593 

In-service  training,  see  Personnel  administra- 
tion, public,  training 

Inspection,  523  ff.;  field,  281  ff.;  see  also 
Regulation,  governmental,  administrative  ap- 
proach 

Institute,  of  Inter-American  Affairs,  243;  of 
Inter- American  Transportation,  243;  of  Pub- 
lic Administration,  33,  450  ff. 

Institutional  administration,  see  Organization, 
staff 

Instruction  training,  see  Supervision,  adminis- 
trative, skills 

Integration,  and  legislative  control,  344  ff.; 
and  organization,  152  ff.;  see  also  Inde- 
pendent regulatory  agencies 

Integrity,  administrative,  see  Ideology,  ad- 
ministrative; Responsibility,  administrative 

Inter- American,  Educational  Foundation,  243; 
Navigation  Corporation,  243 

Interest  groups,  304  ff.t  314  ff.,  375  ff.;  and 
bureaucracy,  314  ff.;  and  independent  regu- 
latory agencies,  see  Independent  regulatory 
agencies;  and  regulation,  see  Regulation, 


Interest  groups — (Continued) 
governmental;  Bureaucracy;  and  service 
state,  98  ff.;  clientele  organization,  318  ff.; 
see  also  Clientele  agencies;  consultation,  334 
ff.;  governmentalization,  316;  'interest  rep- 
resentation, 330  ff.;  staffing  for  point  of 
view,  322  ff.;  types,  314  ff.;  see  also  Chief 
executive;  Information,  administrative;  In- 
tergovernmental relations 

Intergovernmental  relations,  25,  81  ff.;  see 
also  Service  state 

Interior,  Department  of  the,  17,  142  ff.,  186, 
222,  249,  269,  289  ff.,  345,  580,  585,  603 

Internal  Revenue,  Bureau  of,  525 

International,  Association  of  Chiefs  of  Police, 
450;  City  Managers  Association,  24  n.  17, 
450,  494 

Internship,  see  Personnel  administration,  pub- 
lic, training 

Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  61,  113, 
186,  209  n.  2,  215,  216  n.  5,  219,  221  ff., 
228,  232,  318  ff.,  369,  451  ff.,  522  ff.t 
541 

Interviews,  see  Personnel  administration,  pub- 
lic, tests;  Surveys,  administrative 

Investigation,  Federal  Bureau  of,  571;  of  facts, 
see  Budgeting,  justifications;  Policy,  ad- 
ministrative, formulation;  suitability,  563 
n.  24 

Italy,  53 

I 

"J"  programs,  424  ff.,  475 

Jackson,  Andrew,  22,  95,  166  ff. 

James,  William,  cited,  98 

Japan,  451 

Jefferson,  Thomas,  11,  21,  77,  95,  100,  166, 
609;  cited  77,  influence  on  administration, 
12  ff. 

Job,  instruction  training,  see  Supervision,  ad- 
ministrative, skills;  management  training, 
see  Supervision,  administrative,  skills;  re- 
lations training,  see  Supervision,  adminis- 
trative, skills 

Johns  Hopkins  University,  30 

Joint  Chiefs  of  Staff,  194 

Jones,  Jesse,  cited,  257 

Judicial  review,  administrative  courts,  538  ff.; 
administrative  fairness,  531  ff.;  legislative 
standards,  535;  of  administration,  519  ff.; 
political  factors,  542;  scope,  533;  see  also 
Independent  regulatory  agencies;  Regula- 
tion, governmental;  Supreme  Court 

Judiciary,  and  chief  executive,  169  ff. 

Juran,  J.  M.,  cited,  445  ff. 

Justice,  10  ff.;  Department  of,  186,  223,  224, 
261.  580.  610 


630 


INDEX 


Kansas  City,  Mo.,  79,  285 

Kecnan,  Joseph  B.,  327  ff. 

Kefauver,  Representative,  cited,  359 

Keynes,  John  M.,  588 

Kiev,  University  of,  5 

Knoxville,  Tenn.,  285 

Knudscn,  William  S.,  327  ff.;  cited,  54 

Krug,  Julius  A.,  324 


Labor,  Bureau  of,  17;  Department  of,  15  ff., 
142,  186,  201,  222  ff.,  319  ff..  353;  organ- 
ized, see  Interest  groups;  Statistics,  Bureau 
of,  112,  201 

LaFollctte,  Robert,  Sr.,  168 

LaGuardia,  Mayor,  169,  454,  545 

Laissez  fare,  see  Nonintervention,  govern- 
mental 

Land-grant  colleges,  84 

Land-use   planning,  see   Planning,   techniques 

Landis,  James  M.,  529 

Language  sheets,  see  Budgeting,  justifications 

Laski,  Harold  J.,  335 

Latin  America,  243 

Lausche,  Mayor,  169 

Laves,  Walter  H.  C.,  cited,  366  n.   1 

Law,  administrative,  see  Judicial  review;  legal 
approach,  30;  role  of  agency  lawyer,  376 
ff.;  schools,  and  public  service  training,  41; 
see  also  "Rule  of  law";  Due  process  of  law 

Lawyer,  in  government,  547 

Leadership,  administrative,  see  Morale;  po- 
litical, sec  Chief  executive;  sec  also  Or- 
ganization, informal 

League  of  Women  Voters,  112,  307,  546 

Lee,  Ivy,  199 

Legal  profession,  62,  527  ff. 

Legality,  see  Judicial  review 

Legislation,  delegated,  see  Independent  regu- 
latory agencies;  Judicial  review 

Legislative  control,  77  ff.,  339  ff.;  and  ad- 
ministrative accountability,  354  ff.;  and  ad- 
ministrative procedure,  386  ff.;  and  ap- 
pointments, 354  ff.;  and  executive  respon- 
sibility, 354  ff.;  and  independent  regu- 
latory agencies,  223  ff.;  and  integration, 
344  ff.;  and  responsibility,  349  ff.;  diffu- 
sion, 342  ff.;  of  removals,  357  ff.;  over 
administration,  189  ff.;  reform,  358  ff.;  see 
also  Accountability,  fiscal;  Auditing;  Budget- 
ing 

Legislative-executive  relations,  see  Executive- 
legislative  relations 

Legislative  reference  libraries,  29 

Legislative    Reorganization     Act,     621 

Lehman,  Governor,  168 

Liability,  see  Auditing 


Liaison  Office  for  Personnel  Management,  179, 
181  ff.f  549 

Liberty,  10  ff.,  98  ff.;  procedural  safeguards, 
385  ff.;  .see  also  Democratic  administration 

Libraries,  public,  and  planning,   137 

Lilienthal,  David  £.,  47,  285  ff.;  cited,  132 
ff.t  244,  252 

Limited  government,  see  Government,  lim- 
ited 

Lincoln,  Abraham,  167,  601 

Lincoln,  Neb.,  286 

Line,  see  Organization 

Lloyd,  Henry  Demarest,  28 

Lobbyists,  75,  88 

Local  government,  see  Government,  local 

London,  266;  County  Council,  331;  Passen- 
ger Transport  Board,  331 

Lord  Chancellor,  60 

Los  Angeles,  city,  159,  459,  551,  557,  572, 
576;  county,  40,  459,  465 

Lowden,  Governor,  24 

Lowell,  A.  L.,  30 

Loyal  opposition,  administrative,  312   ff. 

Loyalty,  see  Ideology,  administrative;  investi- 
gations, 347  n.  9 

M 

Macaulay  report,  39 

MacLeish,  Archibald,  199 

Macmahon,  Arthur  W.,  43;  cited,  181,  191 

Madison,  James,  21;  cited,  314 

Management,  and  personnel  administration, 
see  Personnel  administration,  public 

Management,  "arms"  of,  23,  178  ff.,  191  ff., 
301,  401  ff.;  see  also  Staff  agencies;  bulle- 
tins, 468  ff.;  definition,  4;  improvement, 
see  Administration,  public,  improvement; 
legislative,  5;  see  also  Legislative  control 

Management,  middle,  400  ff.;  and  operations 
control,  406  ff.;  and  top  direction,  404  ff.; 
approach,  416  ff.;  delegation,  416  ff.;  rec- 
ords, 420;  reporting  schemes,  419  ff.;  tak- 
ing orders,  413  ff.;  see  also  Budgeting; 
Personnel  administration,  public 

Management,  multiple,  see  Management, 
middle 

Management,  private,  3  ff.,  159  ff.t  483;  and 
public  administration,  450  ff.;  and  red  tape, 
55  ff.;  and  unions,  442  ff.;  research,  see 
Management,  scientific 

Management,  principles  of,  see  Administration, 
public,  study;  public,  sec  Administration, 
public 

Management,  scientific,  34  ff.f  398  n.  8;  and 
public  administration,  450  ff.;  see  also 
Taylor,  Frederick  W. 

Management-Labor  Policy  Committee,   337 

Manuals  of  procedure,  570 


INDEX 


631 


Maritime    Commission,    United    States,    221, 

522  ff. 

Marshall,  General,  cited,  399 
Marx,  Karl,  528 

Massachusetts,  545;  early  banking  regula- 
tions, 14 

Master  plan,  see  Planning,  techniques;  Divi- 
sion of,  133  ff. 
Maverick,  Mayor,  169 
Mayo,  Elton  D.,  44  ff.t  437  ff. 
Mayor,  sec  Chief  executive 
McCarl,  Comptroller  General,  615  ff. 
McCormick,  Charles  P.,  412  ff. 
McKellar,  Senator,  258  ff. 
McKinley,  President,  167 
McNarney,  General,  cited,  132 
Measurement,  of  work,  see  Work  measure- 
ment 

Melbourne,  Lord,  cited,  73 
Mercantilism,  13 

Merit  system,  32  ff.,  544  ff.;  growth,  12; 
see  also  Personnel  administration,  public; 
Service  state 

Mernam,  Charles  E.,  23   n.   15;  cited,   14 
Message,  budget,  587  ff.;  combined,  State  of 
the  Union  and  budget,  178,  587  ff.;  State 
of  the  Union,  587  ff. 
Metals  Reserve  Company,  243,  261 
Methods   see   Procedure,   administrative;   Su- 
pervision, administrative,  skills 
Metropolitan  administration,  18  ff. 
Michigan,  549;  Civil  Service  Act,  cited,  494; 

Municipal  League,  40 
Middle  Ages,  264  ff. 

Middle  management,  see  Management,  middle 
Militia,  Act,  521;  state,  82 
Miller  v.  Horton,  534 
Milieu,  John  D.,  43 
Milwaukee,  286 

Ministers'  powers,  sec  Donoughmore  Com- 
mittee 

Minnesota,  549;  University  of,  450,  569;  con- 
ference of  1931,  39 
Mises,  L.  von,  72  ff. 
Mitchel,  Mayor,  448  ff. 
Monroe,  James,  21 
Montgomery  County,  O.,  465 
Mooney,  James  D.,  cited,  5 
Morale,  478  ff.;  and  discipline,  491  ff.;  and 
organization,    495    ff.;    and    specialization, 
496;   building  of,   483  ff.;  definition,  478 
ff.;  factors,   4;  see  also  Democracy,  office; 
Management,   middle;   Organization,   infor- 
mal;  Relationships,  administrative,   theory 
Morality,  administrative,  procedural  protection, 

387  ff.;  see  also  Ideology,  administrative 
Morgan  cases,  535 
Morrison,  Herbert,  64;  cited,  238 
Morstein  Marx,  Fritz,  cited,  539 


Mortgage  Corporation,  242,  249 

Mosher,  William  E.,  450 

Motivation,  see  Organization,  informal 

Muckrakers,  28  ff. 

Multiple  management,  see  Management,  middle 

Municipal,  administration,  growth,  18  ff.; 
Finance  Officers  Association,  450;  politics, 
73  ff.;  research,  24,  27  ff.,  448  ff.;  see  also 
New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research; 
utilities,  523;  see  also  Government  corpo- 
rations 

Mussolini,  53 

Myers  case,  225 

N 

Napoleon,  265 

National,  Association  of  Manufacturers,  112, 
315;  cited,  81;  Civil  Service  League,  546; 
Defense  Act,  126;  Defense  Mediation 
Board,  333  ff.;  Education  Association,  24, 
369  ff.;  Farmers  Union,  sec  Interest  groups; 
Federation  of  Federal  Employees,  488  ff., 
576;  Guard,  82;  Housing  Agency,  90,  153, 
191,  261;  Industrial  Recovery  Administra- 
tion, 321  ff.;  Institute  of  Public  Affairs,  40, 
567,  569  ff.;  Municipal  League,  24,  29,  448; 
Labor  Relations  Board,  20,  61,  221,  526, 
536,  575;  Park  Service,  144,  289  ff.,  585; 
Research  Library,  proposal  for,  50;  Re- 
sources Committee,  see  National  Resources 
Planning  Board;  Resources  Planning  Board, 
127  ff.,  179,  181,  285,  289;  reports,  81; 
Short  Ballot  Organization,  29;  War  Labor 
Board,  128,  333  ff. 

Nationality  organizations,  see  Interest  groups 
"Nation's  budget,"  588 
Natural  resources,  see  Resources,  natural 
Navigation,  Bureau  of,  86 
Navy   Department,   42,    128,    142,    180,   186, 

269,  346,  454,  460,  476,  581 
Nazism,  481;  see  also  Hitler 
Negro  organizations,  see  Interest  groups 
Nelson,  Donald,  327  ff. 
Neutrality,   administrative,   see  Ideology,   ad- 
ministrative 

New  England,  town  government,  9 
New  Orleans,  285 

New  York,  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research,  24, 
27  ff.,  448  ff.;  city,  159,  285,  448  ff.,  551, 
557,  572;  charter  reform,  129  ff.;  Planning 
Commission,  128  ff.;  constitutional  conven- 
tion, 32  ff.,  449;  state,  159,  448  ff.t  533, 
545,    557,   600;    administrative    procedure, 
529  ff.,  540;  University,  569 
Nilcs,  Mary  C.  H.,  cited,  417 
Nonintervention,  governmental,  11  ff.,  98  ff.; 
limits,  15  ff.;  see  also  Bureaucracy;  Plan- 
ning 
Norris,  Senator,  512 


632 


INDEX 


North  Carolina,  465 
North  Dakota,  465 
Northcotc-Trcvelyan  report,  39 
Northwest  Territory,  10 
Northwestern  University,  569 


Oatman,  Miriam  £.,  cited,  63 

Obligations,  financial,  see  Accountability,  fiscal 

O'Brien,  James  C.,  564 

Office,  Management  Association,  National, 
452;  for  Emergency  Management,  23,  152, 
179,  191,  194  ff.;  of  Civilian  Defense,  83; 
of  Contract  Settlement,  193;  of  Defense 
Transportation,  85,  222,  289,  321  ff.;  336 
ff.,  526;  of  Economic  Stabilization,  179, 
191,  193  ff.,  333  ff.;  of  Education,  428; 
of  Government  Reports,  179;  of  Indian 
Affairs,  142  ff.,  318,  580;  of  Price  Admin- 
istration, 128,  217,  222,  269,  321  ff.,  377, 
475,  486  ff.,  529  ff.,  572;  of  Production 
Management,  321  ff.;  of  Scientific  Research 
and  Development,  81,  115;  of  Strategic 
Services,  564;  of  War  Mobilization  and 
Reconversion,  128,  179,  182,  191,  193  ff. 

Officialese,  68  ff. 

Officiousness,  see  Bureaucracy 

Old-Age  and  Survivors  Insurance,  Bureau  of, 
391  ff. 

Olson,  Governor,  168 

Opinion  analysis,  see  Information 

Ordinary  budget,  see  Budgeting 

Ordway,  Samuel  H.,  Jr.,  564 

Organization,  and  change,  297;  and  coordina- 
tion, 152;  and  procedure,  383  ff.;  bases, 
141  ff.,  187  ff.;  bureau,  202  ff.;  charts, 
294  ff.;  definition,  HO  ff.;  departmental, 
184  ff.;  ecclesiastic,  5;  field,  see  Field  or- 
ganization; for  administrative  analysis,  452 
ff.;  guiding  rules,  153  ff.;  hierarchy,  148 
ff.;  human  factor,  43  ff.;  informal,  294  ff., 
and  organized  employees,  313,  informal 
cabinet,  307  ff.,  relationships,  294  ff,  per- 
sonal secretary,  309  ff.;  integration,  152  ff.; 
line,  145  ff.;  of  departments,  184  ff.;  of 
personnel  administration,  547  ff.;  personal, 
296  ff.,  300  ff.;  political  factors,  144  ff., 
188  ff.,  197  ff.-,  span  of  control,  149,  184 
ff.;  staff,  145  ff.,  200  ff.,  298  ff.;  theory, 
32  ff.,  44  ff.i  unity  of  command,  150  ff.; 
working  concepts,  140  ff.;  see  also  Field 
organization;  Morale;  Personnel  adminis- 
tration, public,  training 

Overman  Act,  176,  190 

Overtime  Pay  Act,  605  ff. 

Oxford  University,  5 


Paine,  Thomas,  75 

Palermo,  University  of,  5 

Panama  Railroad  Company,  241,  247,  253 

Paper  work,  see  Auditing;  Procedure,  ad- 
ministrative; Management,  middle,  records 

Paris,  University  of,  5 

Park  Service,  see  National  Park  Service 

Participation,  see  Morale 

Party  government,  see  Chief  executive;  Legis- 
lative control 

Patent  Office,  16 

Patents,  Superintendent  of,  16 

Patronage,  see  Rotation  in  office 

Patten,  Simon,  30 

Pendleton  Act,  22 

Pennock,  J.  Roland,  cited,  60 

Pennsylvania,  159;  Railroad,  199;  University 
of,  30 

Perfectionism,  95  ff. 

Performance,  standards,  see  Administration, 
public,  improvement;  Morale;  tests,  see 
Personnel  administration,  public,  tests 

Periodicity,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting,  prin- 
ciples 

Permanent   Appropriations  Repeal   Act,   600 

Personnel  administration,  public,  544  ff.;  and 
budgeting,  549  ff.;  as  staff  activity,  147; 
central,  548  ff.;  classification,  553  ff.;  com- 
pensation, 553  ff.;  departmental,  550  ff.; 
employee  rating,  446  ff.,  566  n.  27;  em- 
ployee relations,  574  ff.;  employment,  557 
ff.;  examinations,  560  ff.;  grievances,  576; 
growth,  20  ff.;  internship,  569  ff.;  organi- 
zation of,  181  ff.,  547  ff.;  orientation,  570; 
personnel  ceilings,  193,  605  ff.;  placement, 
93  ff.,  566  ff.;  recruitment,  559  ff.;  staffing 
for  point  of  view,  see  Interest  groups; 
suitability  test,  347  n.  9;  tests,  562  ff.; 
training,  567  ff.;  see  also  Administration, 
public,  improvement;  Administration,  pub- 
lic, training;  Discipline;  Government  corpo- 
rations, personnel  control;  Legislative  con- 
trol, of  removals;  Morale;  Organization,  in- 
formal; Planning;  President's  Committee  on 
Civil  Service  Improvement;  Supervision,  ad- 
ministrative, selection  for;  Supervision,  ad- 
ministrative, skills 

Personnel,  federal,  growth,  19;  policy,  public, 
see  Legislative  control,  appointments 

Petroleum  Administration  for  War,  222,  321 
ff»  454 

Pfiffncr,  John  M.,  cited,  434  ff.,  465 

Philadelphia,  159,  285 

Phillips  Petroleum  Company,  185 

Pinchot,    see    Ballinger-Pinchot   controversy 

Pinkerton  Detective  Agency,  581 

Pioneers,  see  Frontier 


INDEX 


633 


Placement,  see  Personnel  administration,  pub- 
lic 

Planning,  administrative)  23,  46  ff.,  123  ff., 
174,  192  ff.;  and  unions,  459  ff.;  see  also 
Policy,  administrative,  formulation;  and  ad- 
ministration, 121  ff.,  181;  and  management, 
131  ff.;  and  operations,  130  ff.;  and  to- 
talitarianism, 125;  as  staff  activity,  146  ff.; 
joint  field,  289  ff.;  legislative,  124;  ma- 
chinery, 126  ff.;  military,  124;  of  adminis- 
trative surveys,  462  ff.;  organizational,  see 
Organization;  personnel,  134  ff.;  public 
relations,  138  ff.;  techniques,  136  ff.;  see 
also  Policy 

Plant  Industry,  Soils,  and  Agricultural  Engi- 
neering, Bureau  of,  113 

Police,  state,  18 

Policy,  administrative,  7  ff.,  198  ff.,  365  ff.t 
and  supervision,  441  ff.,  clearance,  370  ff., 
dynamics  of,  377  ff.,  external  factors,  375 
ff.,  formulation,  88  ff.f  365  ff.,  see  also 
Legislative  control,  Management,  middle; 
administrative  feasibility,  110;  and  adminis- 
tration, 7  ff.,  53  ff.,  72  ff.,  88  ff.,  108  ff., 
158  ff.;  and  interest  groups,  314  ff.;  and 
legislative  control,  339  ff.;  contribution  of 
administrators,  36  ff.;  coordination  of,  182, 
228  ff.;  executive,  and  recruitment,  557  ff.; 
executive-legislative  relations,  170  ff.,  198  ff.; 
fiscal,  26,  102,  586  ff.;  legislative, 7  ff.,  365  ff.; 
planning,  46  ff.,  105  ff.;  political  feasibility, 
109  ff.;  primacy  over  administration,  7  ff. 

Political,  leadership,  see  Chief  executive; 
rights,  of  civil  servants,  493  ff. 

Port  of  London  Authority,  331 

Portland,  Ore.,  385 

POSDCORB,  146 

Post-entry  training,  see  Personnel  administra- 
tion, public,  training 

Post  Office  Department,  82,  84,  135  ff.f  186, 
245,  269,  459,  521,  532,  593,  599 

Postal  administration,  99 

Postmaster  General,  172,  198,  604 

Pound,  Roscoc,  cited,  527  ff. 

Power,  abuse  of,  see  Bureaucracy;  Judicial 
review;  political,  as  cormptive  influence, 
12  ff. 

Pragmatism,  in  administration,  14  ff.,  90  ff., 
102  ff. 

Prc-entry  training,  see  Personnel  administra- 
tion, public,  training 

Prencinradio,  243 

President,  see  Chief  executive 

President's,  Commission  on  Home  Building 
and  Home  Ownership,  81;  Committee  on 
Administrative  Management,  23,  34,  35, 
46,  449,  548  ff.;  cited,  127,  178,  186; 
proposals,  178  ff.,  234  ff.,  288,  540  ff., 


President's — (Continued) 
617 1  Committee  on  Civil  Service  Improve- 
ment, 23,  41  ff.;  cited,  402  ff.;  Committee 
on  Recent  Social  Trends,  81,  450 
Pressure  groups,  see  Interest  groups 
Price   administration,    83;   see   also   Office   of 

Price  Administration 

Prior  authorization,  of  budget,  see  Budget- 
ing, principles 

Procedure,  administrative,  237  ff.,  381  ff., 
414  ff.;  analysis,  392  ff.;  and  legislative 
control,  386  ff.;  and  organization,  383  ff.; 
creation,  392  ff.;  for  grievances,  576;  in- 
stitutional, 389  ff.;  manuals,  570;  stand- 
ardization, 392  ff.;  types,  381  ff.;  working, 
389  ff.;  see  also  Independent  regulator)' 
agencies;  Administrative  Procedure  Act; 
Attorney  General's  Committee  on  Adminis- 
trative Procedure 

Process  chart,  see  Surveys,  administrative 
Production  Credit  Corporations,  243  ff.,  260 
Professional  associations,  of  officials,  24,  31  n. 

9,  315,  450 
Progrcssivism,  29  ff. 
Projects,  see  Budgeting,  by  projects;  Surveys, 

administrative 
Property,    and    interest    groups,    see    Interest 

groups;  ownership,  13 
Protectionism,  see  Tariff,  protective 
Prussia,  265 
Psychology,    public    employment,    67    ff.;   see 

also  Bureaucracy 

Public  administration,  see  Administration,  pub- 
lic; Clearing  House,  24,  40,  370  ff.,  450; 
463,  571;  Service,  35,  450  ff.,  465,  476 
Public,  assistance,  see  Work  Projects  Adminis- 
tration, Works  Progress  Administration; 
Buildings  Administration,  252;  Health 
Service,  United  States,  290,  370,  525  ff.; 
information,  opinion  analysis,  78  ff.;  see 
also  Information 

Public    relations,    and    administrative    policy, 

376;    counselors,    315;    departmental,    199 

ff.;  executive,  170  ff.;  see  also  Information; 

Planning,  public  relations 

Public  reporting,  public  relations  officers,  80; 

see  also  Information 

Public  works,  see  Planning;  Budgeting;  Audit- 
ing; Administration,  270  ff.,  280 
Publicity,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting,  principles 
Purchasing,  governmental,  581;  municipal,  24 


Quartermaster  Corps,  475 
Quasi-departmcnts,  23,  190  ff. 
Quasi-judicial  agencies,  see  Independent  regu- 
latory agencies 


634  INDEX 

Quasi-legislative     agencies,     see    Independent 

regulatory  agencies 
Questionnaires,    see    Coordination,    statistical; 

Surveys,  administrative 


Ramspeck,  Representative^  449;  Committee 
449;  Act,  255 

Randolph,  John,  cited,  609 

Rating,  of  employees,  446  ff. 

Receipts,    public,    see   Accountability,   fiscal 

Recision  Act,  605 

Reclamation,  Bureau  of,  249,  290  ff.,  345 

Reconnaissance,  administrative,  see  Surveys, 
administrative,  types 

Reconstruction  Finance  Corporation,  103,  228, 
241  ff.,  356 

Record  administration,  see  Management,  mid- 
dle, record 

Recruitment,  see  Personnel  administration, 
public 

Red  tape,  see  Bureaucracy;  Procedure,  ad- 
ministrative 

Reed,  Justice,  23,  41,  402  ff. 

Reform,  administrative,  27  ff.;  and  corrup- 
tion, 22;  see  also  Personnel  administration, 
public;  legislative,  see  Legislative  control, 
reform;  Reorganization;  municipal,  448  ff.; 
of  legislative  budget  procedure,  590  ff. 

Regimentation,  see  Bureaucracy 

Regional,  administration,  see  Field  organiza- 
tion; development  authorities,  290  ff.; 
planning  commissions,  289  ff. 

Regulation,  governmental,  522  ff.;  adminis- 
trative approach,  214  ff.;  freedom  under, 
13  ff.;  benefits  of,  113  ff.;  judicial  review, 
107  ff.,  519  ff.;  nature  of,  212  ff.;  see  also 
Bureaucracy;  Intergovernmental  relations 

Regulatory  agencies,  see  Independent  regu- 
latory agencies 

Reiley,  Alan  C.,  cited,  5 

Relationships,  administrative,  see  Budget- 
ing; Personnel  administration,  public;  Plan- 
ning; theory,  44  ff.;  citizen-administrator, 
66  ff.;  executive-legislative,  see  Policy; 
human,  and  management  improvement,  474 
ff.;  informal  organization,  294  ff.;  work- 
ing, see  Supervision,  administrative,  skills 

Relations,  employee,  see  Personnel  administra- 
tion, public,  employee  relations;  public,  see 
Public  relations 

Relief,  see  Work  Projects  Administration; 
Works  Progress  Administration;  and  Re- 
habilitation Administration,  United  Nations, 
555;  recipients,  see  Interest  groups 

Removal,  see  Chief  executive,  legal  powers 


Reorganization,  and  chief  executive,  176  ff.; 
Act  of  1939,  23,  127,  176,  179,  186,  190 
ff.,  234  n.  31,  361,  617;  of  1945,  23,  176, 
180  ff.,  186,  190,  234  n.  31,  361,  617; 
legislative,  78,  358  ff.t  590  ff.,  617  ff.; 
municipal,  31  ff.,  161  ff.t  186  ff.,  192  ff., 
448  ff.;  state,  10,  23  ff.,  31  ff.,  161,  185 
ff.,  192  ff.,  448  ff. 

Reporting,   see   Information,    administrative 

Reports  Act,  193 

Representation,  of  public  interest,  87  ff.;  see 
also  Interest  groups 

Research,  administrative,  see  Administration, 
public;  Information,  administrative;  and 
warfare,  82  ff.;  bureaus,  municipal,  see 
New  York  Bureau  of  Municipal  Research 

Resources,  natural,  exploitation,  14;  see  also 
Service,  state 

Responsibility,  administrative,  37,  90  ff.,  515 
ff.;  and  administrative  policy,  365  ff.;  psy- 
chological factors,  67  ff.;  see  also  Audit- 
ing; Budgeting;  Personnel  administration, 
public;  Organization,  informal;  and  busi- 
ness practice,  504  ff.;  and  discretion,  501 
ff.;  essentials,  501  ff.;  executive,  6,  32  ff., 
158  ff.,  512  ff.,  diffusion,  349  ff.;  legis- 
lative, 507  ff.,  diffusion,  349  ff. 

Retraining  and  Reemployment  Administration, 
193 

Revenue,  see  Accountability,  fiscal 

Review,  budget,  600  n.  37 

Riders,  legislative,  see  Budgeting,  appropria- 
tions 

Right-and-left-hand  chart,  see  Surveys,  ad- 
ministrative 

Rochester  Gas  &  Electric  Corporation,   185 

Rockefeller,  John  D.,  168,  199 

Roethlisbcrger,  Fritz  J.,  437  ff. 

Roman  Catholic  Church,  149;  see  also  Ad- 
ministration, ecclesiastic 

Roosevelt,  Franklin  D.,  23,  75,  168  ff.,  179, 
195,  211,  225,  228,  558;  cited,  163  ff.,  167 

Roosevelt,  Theodore,  25,  161,  167 

Root,  Elihu,  cited,  130 

Rotation  in  office,  11  ff.,  27  ff.,  95;  see  also 
Responsibility,  essentials 

Rubber,  Development  Corporation,  243;  Re- 
serve Company,  243 

"Rule  of  law,"  10  ff.,  58  ff.,  385  ff.;  ex- 
tension of,  522 

Rule-making,  administrative,  519  ff.;  see  also 
Bureaucracy;  Independent  regulatory  agen- 
cies 

Rural    Electrification   Administration,   355   ff. 

Russia,  164  ff.,  178,  316 


St.  Louis,  159 
St.  Paul,  557 


INDEX 


635 


Salamanca,  University  of,  5 

Salaries,  see  Personnel  administration,  public, 
compensation 

San  Francisco,  285  ff.,  572 

Scandinavian  countries,  52 

School  districts,  growth,  10 

Schurz,  Carl,  28 

Scientific  management,  see  Management, 
scientific 

Seasongood,  Mayor,  169 

Seattle,  79 

Secretary,  see  Departmental  system;  personal, 
309  ff. 

Securities  and  Exchange  Commission,  20,  61, 
221  ff.,  261,  31-8  ff.,  522  ff.f  529  ff.,  607 

Selective  Service  System,  83,  522 

Self-restraint,  administrative,   8  ff.,   112   ff. 

Service  activities,  see  Organization,  staff 

Service  ideology,  see  Ideology,  administrative 

Service  rating,  see  Personnel  administration, 
public,  rating 

Service  state,  18,  98  ff. 

Shakespeare,  cited,  52 

Shintoism,  481;  see  also  Japan 

Shipping  Board,  616 

Short  ballot,  32  ff. 

Simo-motion  chart,  see  Surveys,  adminis- 
trative 

Simplification,  Committee  on  Simplification 
of  Procedures,  New  York  City,  454;  pro- 
cedural, 392  ff.;  see  also  Organization; 
Work  simplification 

Sloan,  Alfred  P.,  168 

Smaller  War  Plants  Corporation,  250,  253 

Smith,  Adam,  13,  85;  cited,  502  n.  2 

Smith,  Governor,  168 

Smith,  Harold  D.,  460  ff. 

Smith,  Hubert  L.,  cited,  122 

Social  Science  Research  Council,  450 

Social  Security,  Act,  545;  Board,  114,  145, 
277,  391  ff.,  459 

Social  Workers,  see  Interest  groups 

Society  for  the  Advancement  of  Management, 
5,  452 

Solid  Fuels  Administration,  222 

Solidarity,  professional,  see  Ideology,  adminis- 
trative; Morale 

Somervell,  General,  460 

South  Carolina,  465 

Southern  California,  University  of,  40,  569, 
572 

Soviet  Union,   52,    125;   see  also  Russia 

Span,  of  control,  see  Organization;  of  super- 
vision, 442 

Specialization,  see  Organization;  Morale;  Per- 
sonnel administration,  public 

Specificity,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting,  prin- 
ciples 

Spencer,  Herbert,  15 


Spending   power,  see  Accountability,  fiscal 

Spoils  system,  see  Rotation  in  office 

Spruce  Production  Corporation,  United  States, 
241 

Staff,  see  Administration,  public,  improvement; 
Legislative  control,  reform;  Organization; 
Policy,  administrative,  formulation;  agen- 
cies, 35  ff.,  109  ff.,  180  ff.,  191  ff.,  236  ff.; 
see  also  Budgeting;  Budget  Bureau;  Execu- 
tive Office  of  the  President;  Planning;  con- 
ferences, 206,  446,  455  ff.;  see  also  Man- 
agement, middle;  legislative,  592,  615,  618 

Stalin,  Joseph,  cited,  164  ff. 

Standard  Oil,  of  California,  454 

Standard  operating  procedure,  see  Procedure, 
administrative 

Standardization,  of  procedure,  see  Procedure, 
administrative,  standardization 

Standards,  National  Bureau  of,  16;  of  opera- 
tions, 583;  of  regulation,  see  Independent 
regulatory  agencies;  performance,  s&t 
Morale 

Stassen,  Governor,  168,  545 

State   Department,    117,    186,    194,   457   ff. 

State   government,    see   Government,   state 

States'   rights,  see  Intergovernmental   relations 

Statistical  Reporter,  370 

Steamboat  Inspection  Service,   16,  86 

Stone,  Donald  C.,  cited,  122,  154  ff.,  160, 
281 

Strike,  see  Unions,   government  employee 

Suggestion  systems,  462,  476  ff.;  see  also 
Supervision,  administrative,  and  employee 
initiative 

Sumncr,  William  Graham,  14 

Supervision,  administrative,  421  ff.;  and  em- 
ployee initiative,  444  ff.,  476  ff.;  and  em- 
ployee rating,  446  ff.;  and  management 
improvement,  461  ff.]  and  policy,  4-U  ff.; 
dual,  150,  277  ff.;  functional,  421  ff.; 
institutional  aspects,  423  ff.;  problems,  434 
ff.;  reforms,  434  ff.;  selection  for,  439  ff.; 
skills,  424  ff. 

Supreme  Court,  104,  107,  151,  170,  176, 
228,  330  n.  15,  369,  385  ff..  533  ff.,  613; 
see  also  Humphrey  case 

Surplus  War  Property  Administration,   193 

Surveys,  administrative,  32,  448  ff.;  approach, 
473  ff.;  charting  devices,  472;  interviews, 
469  ff.;  planning,  466  ff.;  reporting,  472 
ff.;  types,  464  ff.;  training,  475  ff. 

Switzerland,  52 

Syracuse,  University,  39,  40,   450,  569 


Taft,   President,  23,   25,   32,   225,   449 
Tariff,   Commission,   United   States,   20;   pro- 
tective, 15  ff. 
Tarver,  Representative,  cited,  350 


636 


INDEX 


Tax  Court  of  the  United  States,  61,  539  ff. 

Taxpayers'  leagues,  see  Interest  groups 

Taylor,  Frederick  W.,  34,  398  n.  8,  421  ff., 
451  ff.,  466 

Teamwork,  see  Morale;  Organization,  infor- 
mal; Relationships,  administrative,  theory 

Techniques,  see  Administration,  public,  im- 
provement; Procedure,  administrative 

Technology,  administrative,  436;  and  ad- 
ministration, 18  ff.;  see  also  Bureaucracy; 
Field  organization 

Tennessee,  185;  Valley  Authority,  18,  46  ff., 
94,  132  ff.,  142,  228,  240  ff.,  275,  289  ff.. 
486,  555  ff.,  567,  585,  593,  609  ff.,  615  ff. 

Terms,  staggered,  see  Independent  regulatory 
agencies,  types  of 

Territories  and  Island  Possessions,  Division 
of,  142 

JTocqueville,  de,  cited,  86 

Totalitarianism,  see  Morale;  in  wartime  gov- 

'-ernmcnt,  98  ff. 

Towne,  Henry  R.,  451 

Trade,  associations,  see  Interest  groups; 
unions,  see  Interest  groups;  Unions 

Trades  Union  Congress,  337  ff. 

Training,  see  "J"  programs;  Personnel  ad- 
ministration, public,  training;  Surveys, 
training;  Within  Industry  Service,  424  ff., 
568 

Transfers,  of  funds,  see  Budgeting 

Transportation  Act,  230  n.  24 

Treasurer,  of  the  United  States,  see  Budgeting 

Treasury  Department,  186,  244  ff.,  250  ff., 
269  ff.,  286,  389  ff.,  455,  558,  579  ff. 

Tripartite  boards,  see  Interest  groups,  repre- 
sentation 

Truman,  President,  166,  449;  Committee,  449 

U 

Uhrbrock,  Dr.,  cited,  561  n.  22 
Undersecretary,  see  Departmental   system 
Unification,    of    structure,    see    Organization; 

Integration;  Coordination 
Unions,    government    employee,     313,     442 

ff.,  487  ff.,  574  ff. 

United  Public  Workers  of  America,  576 
Unity,  of  budget,  see  Budgeting,  principles 
University  administration,  see  Administration, 

college 

Universities,  and  administration,  448  ff.,  see 
also  Administration,  public,   training;   and 
public  service,  559  ff.;  contribution  to  ad- 
ministration, 30  ff. 
Urwick,  Lyndall,  46;  cited,  164 
Utilities,  see  Government  corporations;  Mu- 
nicipal utilities 


Valley  Authorities,  290  ff.;  see  also  Tennessee 

Valley  Authority 
Vandenberg,  Senator,  cited,  357 
Veterans  Administration,   142,  269,  318  ff., 

459 

Veterans'   organizations,   see  Interest   groups 
Virginia,  465;  University  of,  454 
Vouchers,  see  Auditing 

W 

Wage  formula,  see  Personnel  administration, 
public,  compensation 

Wallace,  Henry  A.,  189,  356 

Watsh-Healey  Act,  581 

Walter-Logan  bill,  218  n.  6,  528  ff. 

War,  Assets  Administration,  269;  Department, 
42,  82,  126,  128,  132,  142,  180,  186, 
241,  249,  269,  289  ff.,  345,  346,  372,  419, 
454  ff.,  460,  475,  476,  532,  564,  581; 
see  also  Army  Service  Forces;  Army  Corps 
of  Engineers;  Finance  Corporation,  241; 
Food  Administration,  128,  222,  321  ff., 
350,  454;  Manpower  Commission,  191,  194 
ff.,  222,  289,  337,  357,  424  ff.,  568; 
powers  of  the  President,  101;  Powers  Acts, 
176,  190  ff.;  Production  Board,  79,  128, 
191,  194  ff.,  215,  217,  222,  261,  274,  280, 
289,  321  ff.,  372,  454,  575;  Shipping  Ad- 
ministration, 86,  526 

Warrants,  see  Auditing 

Warren,  Governor,  168 

Washington,  D.  C.,  572 

Washington,  George,  12,  21,  166,  521 

Wayne  University,  40,  569 

Weimar  Constitution,  494 

Welfare,  see  Relief;  state,  see  Service  state 

Western  Electric  studies,  45  ff. 

Whigs,  22 

White,  Leonard  D.,  40;  cited,  100,  189,  473 

Whittlesey,  Elisha,  cited,  611 

Wilcox,  Francis  O.,  cited,  366  n.  1 

Williams,  Aubrey,  355  ff. 

Willoughby,  William  F.,  cited,   145 

Wilmerding,   Lucius,  Jr.,  cited,   601,   614 

Wilson,  Woodrow,  23,  25,  30,  53,  167,  195, 
224,  613 

Winnetka,  111.,  185  ff. 

Wisconsin,  29;  University  of,  30 

Women's,  Bureau,  318  ff.;  Christian  Tem- 
perance Union,  see  Interest  groups;  organi- 
zations, see  Interest  groups 

Wolcott,  Leon  O.,  44 

Woolton,  Lord,  101,  337  ff. 

Work-distribution  chart,  see  Surveys,  ad* 
minis  trative 

Workload,  see  Work  measurement