Skip to main content

Full text of "English public finance from the revolution of 1688. With chapters on the Bank of England"

See other formats


/lERKELKY 

LIBRARY 

UNIVERSITY  Of 
CALIFORhtU 


BUR.  OF  INT. 
REIJVTIONS 


UWIV.    OF 

WITK 


THE  LIBRARY 

OF 

THE  UNIVERSITY 

OF  CALIFORNIA 

RIVERSIDE 


ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 


Digitized  by  tine  Internet  Arciiive 

in  2008  witii  funding  from 

IVIicrosoft  Corporation 


littp://www.arcliive.org/details/englislipublicfinOOfisk 


(0  <^  1^1  n^iu 

ENGLISH 
PUBLIC   FINANCE 

FROM  THE  REVOLUTION  OF  1688 


WITH  CHAPTERS  ON  THE 
BANK  OF  ENGLAND 


BY 

HARVEY  E.  FISK 

OF  THE  STAFF  OF  THE  BANKERS  TRUST  COMPANY 
NEW  YORK 


LONDON 
SIR    ISAAC    PITMAN    &    SONS,    LTD. 
PARKER  STREET,  KINGSWAY,  W.C.2 

BATH,     MELBOURNE,     TORONTO,     NEW     YORK 
1921 


Hr/oii 
F^8 


DUrJ.  OF  INT. 
RELATIONS 


This  book  was  originally  issued  by  the 
Bankers  Trust  Company  of  New  York  for 
private  circulation,  and  it  is  through  the 
courtesy  of,  and  by  arrangement  with  this 
corporation,    that    this    edition    is    published. 


Copyright  in  U.S.A.  by  Bankers  Trust  Company,  New  York. 


PREFACE 


fillK.   JF 
NT.  RELi 


"  States,  like  individuals,  who  observe  their 
engagements  are  respected  and  trusted." 

— Alexander  Hamilton. 

This  book  is  intended  to  give  in  form  for  ready  reference 
the  salient  facts  in  regard  to  the  finances  of  the  United 
Kingdom. 

The  earher  chapters  tell  the  financial  story  of  the  critical 
period  of  the  war  from  the  fateful  4th  August,  1914,  when  war 
was  declared,  to  the  budget  speech  of  Chancellor  Chamberlain 
on  19th  April,  1920,  which  so  ably  dealt  with  the  financial 
problems  of  the  reconstruction  period.  The  later  chapters 
discuss  the  revenue,  expenditure  and  debt  prior  to  1914  and 
England's  methods  of  financing  from  the  time  of  Wilham  the 
Conqueror.  Present  day  financial  methods  are  traced  back 
to  their  origins  in  these  early  days. 

The  activities  of  the  Bank  of  England  are  so  closely 
interwoven  with  the  operations  of  the  Treasury  that  to 
apprehend  clearly  Great  Britain's  pubhc  finance  one  should 
have  knowledge  of  the  history,  the  functions,  and  the  opera- 
tions of  the  Bank  ;  therefore  several  chapters  have  been 
devoted  to  these  matters. 

Almost  without  exception  the  statements  of  fact  contained 
in  this  book,  especially  those  having  to  do  with  its  main 
purpose — ^pubhc  finance — ^are  based  upon  a  study  of  official 
documents.  Where  necessary  to  depend  upon  secondary 
sources  care  has  been  taken  to  refer  only  to  those  admittedly 
authoritative. 

We  are  hopeful  that  this  book  may  contribute  to  a  better 
understanding  of  Great  Britain's  present  financial  problems 
and  how  they  are  being  solved,  and  that  it  may  prove  to  be  a 
useful  work  of  reference  for  our  friends. 

Bankers  Trust  Company, 

New  York,  June.   1920, 


CONTENTS 


Preface  .... 

I.     "  1920  " 

II.     "1914" 

III.  War   Costs   and    How    They 

Were   Met 

IV.  The  War  Debt 

V.     How     the      Banks     Helped 

Finance  the  War 
VI.     The  War  Credit  Structure 
VII.    Crown  Finance 
VIII.     Revenues  of  the  Anglo-saxon 
Kings.         .... 
IX.     The  King's  Prerogative 
X.     Crown  Revenues  Subsequent 

TO  Norman  Period 

XI.     Crown  Debts  .... 

XII.  Constitutional   Government 

Developed  by  Control  of 

THE  Purse  .... 

XIII.  England  After   the   Revolu- 

tion OF  1688 

XIV.  War  and  Debt 

XV.     Early    Forms    of    Unfunded 

Debt    ..... 

XVI.    Early  Forms  of  Funded  Debt 

XVII.     State  Lotteries  and  Lottery 

Loans  ..... 

XVIII.     The  Sinking  Funds 

XIX.    Early  Refunding  Operations 

XX.     Financing  the  Great  French 

War 

XXI.     Revenue  and  Expenditure    . 
XXII.    Peace  and  Social  Betterment 


PAGB 

V 

1 

4 

(1914-1920) 

11 

(1914-1920) 

19 

(1914-1920) 

33 

(1914-1920) 

39 

(1066-1688) 

47 

49 

(1066-1688) 

53 

(1154-1688) 

55 

(1216-1688) 

62 

(1066-1688) 

66 

(1688-1920) 

74 

(1688-1817) 

79 

(1688-1707) 

83 

(1688-1727) 

87 

(1694-1826) 

93 

(1717-1920) 

101 

(1739-1817) 

105 

(1793-1817) 

108 

(1688-1817) 

118 

(1817-1914) 

122 

VIU 


CONTENTS 


XXIII.  The  Ancient  Exchequer 

XXIV.  The  Modern  Fiscal  System 

XXV.    Concluding  Thought  and  Deductions 


PAGB 

130 
134 
142 


THE  BANK  OF  ENGLAND. 

I.  A  Banking  Evolution 

II.  The  Genesis  of  Banking  . 

III.  The  Early  History  of  the  Bank 

IV,  The  Bank  and  the  Great  French  War 
V.  The  Joint-Stock  Banks    . 

VI.    The  Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844 
VII.    The  Government  of  the  Bank 
VIII.    The  Scotch  and  Irish  Banks  . 

(The  Bank  in  the  Great  World  War.  For 
part  taken  see  Chapter  V,  page  33,  and 
Chapter  VI,  page  39.) 

Tables — 

National  Debt  Statement,  31st  March,  1920 
Quotations  :    Consols  and  Bank  of      England    Stock 

1697-1919.     British  Funds  :  1910-1919 
Money  Rates     . 
Treasury  Bills — Discount  Rates 
England's  Sovereigns 
Authorities 

Index  and  Glossary 


147 
150 

157 
161 
166 
169 

174 
179 


181 

188 
193 
193 
194 
195 

199 


Statistical  statements  in  the  text  and  tables  as  a  rule  are 
given  in  round  figures. 


ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 


CHAPTER  I 

"  1920  " 

The  great  world  war  of  1914-1919,  terminated  by  the 
acceptance  by  H.M.  King  George  V,  on  31st  July,  1919, 
of  the  Peace  of  Versailles,  signed  28th  June,  1919,  cost 
Great  Britain  over  ^^lO.OOO  million  sterling.  If  we  add  to  this 
sum  the  war  expenditures  of  the  British  self-governing 
Dominions:  Canada,  £407  million  ;  Australia,  £379  million  ; 
New  Zealand  about  £76  million  ;  Union  of  South  Africa, 
£60  million,  and  little  Newfoundland  about  £3  million  ; 
together  with  the  war  expenses  of  the  Crown  Colonies,  and 
India's  war  expenditure  of  £20  million  and  contribution  of 
£100  million,  we  arrive  at  a  grand  total  for  the  British 
Empire  of  over  £11,000  million.  This  was  an  expenditure 
made  necessaxy  by  the  war  in  excess  of  what  would  have 
been  the  expenditiire  for  the  period  on  the  basis  of  the 
pre-war  budget. 

An  analysis  of  the  total  expenditure  of  the  United  Kingdom 
from  1688  to  1920  discloses  the  amazing  fact  that  for  the 
six  fiscal  years,  beginning  31st  March,  1914,  and  ending 
31st  March,  1920,  the  expenditure  of  the  Government  actually 
exceeded  the  total  expenditure  for  the^  two  and  a  quarter 
centuries  preceding  1914.  The  exact  figures  are  :  for  the 
226  years,  £10.944  million  ;  for  the  six  years,  £11,268  million. 

*  In  making  this  comparison,  however,  we  should  not  lose  sight  of 
the  fact  that  the  purchasing  power  of  the  £  sterling  has  fluctuated 
greatly  during  this  period,  and  that  frequently,  particularly  in  the 
early  years,  a  given  sum  would  procure  much  more  in  services  and 
in  commodities  than  would  be  the  case  to-day.  This  fact  should  be 
borne  in  mind  all  through  these  pages  wherever  similar  money 
comparisons  are  made. 

1 

1— (1823) 


2  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

The  people  of  Great  Britain  paid  into  the  coffers  of  the 
Government  in  taxes  and  other  revenue  collections  over 
36  per  cent,  of  this  vast  sum  of  more  than  eleven  thousand 
million  sterling.     The  other  64  per  cent,  was  borrowed. 

The  war  borrowings  of  Great  Britain  at  their  maximum, 
31st  December,  1919,  amounted  at  par  value  of  securities 
issued  to  £7,368  million,  £6,011  million  fmnished  by  her  own 
people,  £1,027  million  borrowed  in  and  from  the  United 
States,  and  £330  million  borrowed  from  other  foreign  nations 
and  from  the  Dominions.  On  the  other  hand,  Great  Britain 
had  then  loaned  to  the  Dominions  £186  million  and  to  her 
allies  £1,666  million,  so  that  the  amount  loaned  abroad 
exceeded  by  £495  million  the  amount  borrowed  abroad. 

Thus  we  find  that  the  46  million  people  of  the  British 
Isles  raised  entirely  from  their  own  resources  a  net  amount 
of  £9,911  million,  over  £215  for  each  one  of  their  number. 

For  the  active  war  period  covering  the  five  fiscal  years 
ending  31st  March,  1919,  from  22^  per  cent,  to  34|  per  cent, 
of  the  expenditure  was  raised  from  taxation,  other  revenue 
collections,  and  war  contributions.  In  the  fiscal  year  ended 
31st  March,  1920,  taxes  and  other  revenue  produced  about 
65  per  cent,  of  the  aggregate  budget  of  £1,662  million,  while 
receipts  from  war  contributions,  sales  of  war  property,  and 
income  from  trading  undertakings  yielded  about  16  per  cent., 
leaving  less  than  20  per  cent,  to  be  provided  from  loans. 
Indications  now  are  that  in  the  current  fiscal  year  (1920- 
1921)  the  budget  will  balance  not  only  without  any  addition 
to  the  debt  but,  if  the  present  plans  of  the  Government 
materialize,  with  a  substantial  surplus  for  the  reduction  of 
debt. 

The  national  wealth  of  Great  Britain,  or,  as  some  econo- 
mists prefer  to  say,  the  national  capital,  at  the  beginning 
of  the  war  is  estimated  to  have  been  £14,500  million.  There 
has  probably  been  no  actual  addition  during  the  war.  On 
the  contrary,  doubtless,  there  has  been  some  depletion  therein. 
However,  measured  by  the  paper  pound  sterling  of  to-day 
we  may  quite  conservatively  take  £24,000  million  as  the 


"  1920  "  3 

figure  with  which  to  compare  the  £8,078  million  to  which 
the  debt  grew  from  the  pre-war  figure  of  £711  miUion  ;  giving 
us  a  ratio  of,  say,  33^  per  cent,  of  debt  to  wealth.  The 
debt  charge  for  interest  and  management  is  now  about  £360 
million,  comparing  with  £24  million  before  the  war.  The 
present-day  charge  is  about  10  per  cent,  of  the  national 
income  estimated  to  be  £3,600^  million. 

Having  in  mind  these  statistics,  so  vast  as  to  be  almost 
beyond  comprehension,  it  will  be  of  interest  to  know  the 
conditions  under  which  they  developed  and  the  means  used 
to  handle  the  problems  of  war  finance. 

^  This  was  the  estimate  made  by  Sir  Leo  G.  Chiozza-Money  before 
the  Income  Tax  Commission  in  September,  1919,  which  he  thought 
too  low  "  if  the  nation  were  in  lor  a  trade  boom  "  (answer  to  question 
11,137).  The  League  of  Nations  has  since  estimated  the  British 
national  income  at  ;^112  10s.  a  head  on  the  population  of  46J  million, 
or,  say,  ;(5,200  million.  By  some  authorities  this  estimate  is  thought 
to  be  a  better  one  than  that  of  Sir  Leo. 


CHAPTER  II 

"  1914" 

It  was  the  turn  of  the  business  year.  The  cloud  of  pessimism 
which  had  overhung  the  international  finance  markets  since 
the  outbreak  of  the  Balkan  wars  in  1912  seemed  about  to 
disappear. 

The  half-yearly  settlements  had  passed  over  smoothly  in 
the  chief  money  centres  of  Europe.  The  Bank  of  England 
and  all  the  great  central  banks  on  the  Continent  were  in 
strong  credit  condition.  Some  of  these  banks  had  accumu- 
lated reserves  beyond  anything  hitherto  known.  In  fact,  the 
accumulations  of  gold  were  becoming  so  great  as  to  indicate 
that  a  great  revival  in  trade  might  be  expected.  Deposits 
in  the  banks  of  the  United  Kingdom  were  heavier  than  at 
any  time  in  their  history,  amounting  to  about  /^1,150  million, 
an  increase  in  the  fifteen  years  since  the  beginning  of  the 
Boer  War  of  over  ^^300  million. 

The  open  market  rate  of  discount  in  London  had  averaged 
in  the  previous  six  months  £2  10s.  per  cent.  ;  lower  than  for 
any  year  since  1908,  when  the  average  rate  for  the  year  was 
£2  5s.  7d.  per  cent.  ;  and  with  that  exception  lower  than  at 
any  period  since  1898.  This  condition  was  in  great  contrast  to 
that  which  had  characterized  the  money  markets  in  1912  and 
1913,  when  the  discount  rates  had  been  high — averaging  £3 
lis.  6d.  per  cent,  in  the  former  year,  and  £4  6s.  lOd.  per  cent, 
in  the  latter  year.  These  high  rates  in  large  part  had  been 
due  to  the  heavy  demands  made  upon  the  capital  of  the  world 
for  the  expenses  of  the  Balkan  wars  and  the  dislocation  of 
trade  through  Southern  Europe  because  of  these  wars  and  for 
the  subsequent  rehabilitation  of  the  war-torn  territory. 
Commodity  prices  in  these  years  had  been  high  and  investment 
seciu^ity  prices  low. 

With  1914  had  come  a  change  in  this  situation  and  events 
appeared  to  be  favouring  a  revival  in  the  securities  markets 

4 


"1914"  5 

with  less  active  commodities  markets.  England  had  enjoyed 
one  of  the  best  six  months  business  on  record  in  her  foreign 
trade,  even  though  it  had  been  conducted  on  a  somewhat 
lower  price  level  than  in  the  previous  year.  At  the  moment 
trade  was  quiet.  It  was  estimated  that  during  the  half  year 
England  had  invested  over  £100  miUion  abroad.  Her  total 
investments  abroad  were  estimated  to  be  not  less  than  ;f4,000 
milHon,  while  her  annual  income  from  these  investments,  from 
freights  paid  for  carrying  foreign  goods  in  British  ships,  and 
from  banking  charges,  was  estimated  at  £350  milUon. 

As  we  have  already  seen,  her  national  debt  was  only  £711 
milhon,  less  than  five  per  cent,  of  her  estimated  national 
wealth  of  £14,500  million. 

Therefore,  from  every  point  of  view,  England  in  July, 
1914,  was  in  a  strong  financial  condition.  Her  people  were 
prosperous.  The  welfare  of  even  the  humblest  classes  had 
been  made  the  subject  of  important  governmental  action, 
while  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  David  Lloyd  George, 
had  given  notice  of  his  intention  to  bring  forward  a  great  pro- 
gramme of  land  reform.  Relations  with  her  Overseas  Empire 
were  never  closer  or  more  cordial.  Earnest  efforts  were  being 
made  to  work  out  some  plan  for  representation  of  the  great 
Dominions  in  an  Imperial  Parhament  or  for  some  equivalent 
arrangement.  The  only  serious  pohtical  situation  was  the 
perennial  one  of  Ireland,  where  preparations  for  armed 
resistance  by  the  Ulsterites  to  Mr.  Asquith's  proposed  Home 
Rule  plans  gave  the  Government  considerable  anxiety. 

War  Breaks — Emergency  Measures 

On  the  23rd  July  came  the  news  of  Austria's  peremptory 
ultimatum  to  Serbia,  on  the  25th  Serbia's  reply,  and  on 
the  28th  the  starthng  advices  that  Austria-Hungary  had 
declared  war  on  Serbia.  Money  began  to  tighten  ;  the  stock 
markets  became  weak.  On  the  1st  August,  Germany  and 
Russia  were  at  war.  The  foreign  bourses  were  in  a  state  of 
panic.  I^ndon  and  New  York  were  the  only  important  open 
markets.     They  were   flooded   with   international  securities. 


6  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

Between  20th  July  and  30th  July  Consols  fell  six  points,  India 
3^'s  four,  French  Rentes  five,  home  rails  from  five  to  fifteen 
points.  American  rails  broke  heavily.  Canadian  Pacific  sold 
off  25J  points.  South  Americans  dropped  from  four  to 
twenty-four  points.  Still  England  was  not  involved.  On  the 
following  day  the  Stock  Exchange  closed.  The  newspapers  of 
the  day  reported  that  "  paralysis,  not  panic,"  was  the  word 
which  defined  conditions.  On  1st  August  France  ordered  a 
general  mobilization  following  a  peremptory  note  from 
Germany  on  31st  July  demanding  that  she  define  her  attitude 
within  twelve  hours.  On  this  same  day  German  troops 
occupied  Luxemburg,  and  on  the  4th  Germany  had  started  her 
troops  across  Belgium.  At  11  p.m.  of  the  4th  Great  Britain 
entered  the  lists  in  defence  of  Belgian  neutrality  in  accordance 
with  her  treaty  obhgations. 

Fortunately  for  the  financial  world  these  events  were 
taking  place  at  the  time  of  the  London  Bank  Hohday,  which 
fell  on  Monday,  the  3rd  August.  One  of  the  first  steps  taken 
was  to  extend  the  holiday  to  the  7th.  This  gave  time  in  which 
to  take  remedial  measures.  On  31st  July  the  Bank  rate  had 
been  raised  to  8  per  cent.  On  the  following  day  it  was 
raised  to  10  per  cent.  Naturally,  on  the  eve  of  the  holiday 
many  people  had  required  money  for  their  week-end  payments 
and  holiday  expenses.  This  caused  a  demand  on  the  banks 
for  gold,  for  it  will  be  remembered  Bank  of  England  notes 
are  not  issued  in  denominations  of  less  than  five  pounds. 
The  joint-stock  banks  declined  to  pay  out  gold,  telling  their 
patrons  to  go  to  the  Bank  of  England.  This  unprecedented 
action  very  naturally  frightened  the  public  and  stimulated 
their  desire  for  gold,  leading  to  heavy  denaands  being  made 
upon  the  Bank. 

During  the  extended  holiday  important  steps  were  taken 
to  insure  the  stability  of  the  financial  structure. 

The  Currency  Notes 

Provision  was  made  to  issue  Government  notes  in  denom- 
inations of  £1  and  of  10  shillings.     They  were  issued  by  the 


1914 


Bank  of  England  as  agent.  The  plan  was  to  lend  a  supply  of 
such  notes  to  each  bank  up  to  20  per  cent,  of  its  deposits. 
For  this  advance  the  banks  were  to  be  taxed  at  the  rate  of 
5  per  cent,  per  annum  upon  the  par  value  of  the  notes  borrowed. 
The  banks  were  thus  provided  with  funds  for  over  the  counter 
payments. 

The  Moratorium 

The  next  step  was,  on  5th  August,  to  declare  a  hmited 
moratorium — ^that  is,  a  limited  period  during  which  creditors 
could  not  demand  payment  from  those  indebted  to  them. 
This  was  at  first  for  one  month,  afterwards  extended  to  three 
months. 

Protecting  the  Acceptance  Market 

The  most  important  action  at  this  time  was  the  provision 
made  on  12th  August,  that  the  Bank  of  England,  under 
Government  guarantee  against  loss  to  itself  for  so  doing,  should 
discount  pre-moratorium  bills,  whether  drawn  by  enemy  aliens 
or  by  others,  without  recourse  to  the  holder,  "  giving  the 
acceptor  the  opportunity  until  further  notice  of  postponing 
payment,  interest  being  payable  in  the  meantime  at  2  per 
cent,  over  bank  rate."  This  offer  applied  not  only  to  such 
bills  of  exchange  as  were  customarily  discounted  by  the 
Bank  but  also  to  other  good  trade  bills  and  foreign  and 
colonial  acceptances. 

A  moment's  reflection  will  show  how  all  important  this 
action  was  and  also  the  importance  of  the  subsequent  arrange- 
ments for  securing  a  free  market  for  bills  of  exchange.  For 
years  London  had  been  the  banker  for  the  world.  The  system 
of  acceptances  had  helped  to  bring  this  about.  If  a  coffee 
grower  in  South  America  sold  coffee  to  New  York  or  to  Berlin  ; 
if  a  sugar  producer  in  Cuba  or  in  Java  sold  sugar  in  Constan- 
tinople or  in  Paris  ;  if  an  Indian  merchant  sold  articles  of 
luxury  ;  the  Chinaman,  tea  ;  the  American  or  the  Egyptian, 
cotton ;  the  settlements  were  almost  invariably  made  through 
London.  The  Chinaman  might  sell  his  tea  in  New  York,  but 
he  would  arrange  for  payment  through  London.     The  New 


8  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

York  tea  buyer  through  his  bank  in  New  York  would  engage  a 
London  Acceptance  House  or  Bank  to  pay  the  Chinese 
merchant  by  accepting  a  draft  which  that  merchant  would 
draw  on  the  New  York  buyer  through  London.  To  meet  his 
obhgation  the  New  Yorker  would  perhaps  buy  a  bill  which  a 
wheat -grower  in  Minnesota  was  drawing  on  London  to  pay  for 
wheat  which  had  gone  to  France. 

These  bills  coming  in  from  all  parts  of  the  world  were 
mutually  cancelling  each  other,  while  during  the  period  they 
had  to  run  they  were  considered  the  choicest,  the  most  hquid 
asset,  next  to  actual  cash,  which  a  bank  could  hold.  If  a  bank 
required  money  to  meet  an  unexpected  demand  it  need  only 
offer  a  block  of  bills  in  the  market  and  thus  could  immediately 
obtain  the  funds  required. 

When  war,  involving  so  many  of  the  great  mercantile 
nations,  was  unexpectedly  declared,  the  banks  suddenly  found 
their  assets  "  frozen  " — entirely  unavailable.  Worse  than 
this,  there  were  bills  in  transit  which  they  and  the  acceptance 
houses  were  obligated  to  accept  upon  arrival  and  there  were 
miUions  in  value  coming  due  day  by  day  which  they  were 
obligated  on  behalf  of  clients  to  pay.  Manifestly  this  was  the 
great  financial  problem  requiring  instant  attention.  This 
situation  was  met  first  of  all  as  already  stated,  by  providing  a 
market  with  the  Bank  of  England  for  the  pre -moratorium 
bills.  A  few  weeks  later,  on  5th  September,  this  was  followed 
by  a  further  provision  whereby  acceptors  who  were  unable 
to  meet  the  pre-moratorium  bills  at  maturity  received  the 
necessary  funds  from  the  Bank  of  England  at  2  per  cent, 
over  bank  rate.  By  this  process  endorsers  on  the  bill  were 
released.  The  loans  made  to  the  accepting  houses  were,  for 
the  most  part,  to  constitute  a  second  and  not  a  first  claim 
upon  their  assets.  This  greatly  increased  the  negotiability 
of  post -moratorium  biUs  accepted  by  the  same  houses. 

Treasury  Bills  Issued 

On  19th  August  tenders  were  asked  for  £15  million  Treasury 
Bills  to  provide  for  the  immediate  needs  of  the  Government 


"  1914  "  9 

in  connection  with  these  operEdions.  These  bills,  dated 
22nd  August,  represented  the  first  pubhc  issue  of  securities  for 
financing  the  war. 

To  obviate  the  risk  of  transporting  gold  across  the  ocean 
it  was  allowed  to  accumulate  for  accovmt  of  the  Bank  of 
England  in  America  at  Ottawa,  in  South  Africa  at  Cape  Town, 
in  Australia  and  in  India.  Credits  were  granted  by  the  Bank 
against  such  deposits. 

The  Stock  Exchange  Loans 

These  matters  having  been  arranged  it  was  necessary  to 
protect  the  Stock  Exchange  situation.  On  31st  October, 
Government  measures  of  assistance  were  announced.  These 
provided  for  the  extension  of  bank  loans  to  members  of  the 
Stock  Exchange,  until  a  year  after  the  war,  and  with  no 
increase  in  margin.  Other  lending  institutions  not  able  to  give 
such  long  credits  were  permitted  to  obtain  advances  from  the 
Bank  of  England  on  Stock  Exchange  securities  up  to  60  per 
cent,  of  their  value  on  27th  July.  Such  loans  also  were  to 
run  until  a  year  after  the  war. 

Advances  to  Export  Merchants 

On  4th  November,  a  very  interesting  arrangement  waS 
made  between  the  Government,  the  Banks,  and  the  Association 
of  Chambers  of  Commerce  of  the  United  Kingdom  to  promote 
the  export  trade.  To  solvent  traders  were  to  be  advanced 
funds  equivalent  to  50  per  cent,  of  moneys  owing  to  them 
by  debtors  resident  abroad,  these  advances  to  be  used  by  the 
traders  to  continue  their  business  and  pay  their  commercial 
debts  to  other  traders  and  manufacturers.  It  was  under- 
stood that  the  moneys  provided  were  not  to  be  taken  by 
the  banks  to  reduce  loans  or  overdrafts  or  to  pay  bank 
acceptances,  but  were  to  be  solely  a  new  credit  free  for  meeting 
the  purely  trade  obligations  of  the  borrower  and  in  pushing 
his  business  as  rapidly  as  possible.  Any  loss  was  to  be  borne, 
75  per  cent,  by  the  Government  and  25  per  cent,  by  the 
accepting  banks. 


10  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

Similarly,  the  cotton  trade  was  encouraged.  On  14th 
November  the  Government  arranged  a  fund  to  be  used  to 
enable  borrowers  to  meet  market  differences.  The  payment  of 
the  advances  was  guaranteed  as  to  50  per  cent,  by  the  Govern- 
ment, 25  per  cent,  by  the  Liverpool  Cotton  Association, 
and  25  per  cent,  by  the  lending  bank. 

Success  Attending  These  Efforts 

Such  were  the  principal  emergency  measures  taken  during 
1914  to  insure  as  nearly  as  possible  an  uninterrupted  progress 
of  the  banking  and  mercantile  community.  Although  the 
moratorium  was  not  formally  declared  ended  until  4th 
November,  we  have  the  word  of  Sir  Edward  Holden  as 
authority  that  actually,  as  far  as  the  banks  were  concerned, 
"  they  came  from  under  it  "  in  September.  The  year  closed 
with  a  heavy  increase  in  deposits  and  with  a  large  increase  in 
the  gold  reserve  of  the  Bank  of  England,  which  after  dropping 
from  ;^40  million  on  15th  July  to  £11  million  on  8th  August, 
became  £69  million  on  30th  December.  So  that  the  proportion 
of  reserve  to  liabilities,  after  dropping  from  52J  per  cent,  in 
July  to  \A\  per  cent,  in  August,  increased  to  33|  per  cent, 
on  30th  December.  At  the  close  of  the  year  money  was  a 
drug  on  the  market — ^three  months  bills  being  quoted  at 
2|  per  cent. 

At  the  close  of  1914  it  was  estimated  that  some  £84  million 
of  special  loans  of  various  kinds  were  being  carried  for  the 
Government  by  the  Bank.  This  total  included  pre- 
moratorium  bills,  advances  to  traders  and  others  after  the 
expiration  of  the  moratorium,  sums  lent  on  Stock  Exchange 
securities,  and  so  on.  In  addition  were  the  amounts  being 
carried  by  the  joint-stock  banks. 


CHAPTER   III 

WAR  COSTS  AND   HOW  THEY  WERE   MET 

(1914-1920) 

Having  reviewed  the  financial  measures  adopted  at  the 
beginning  of  the  war  to  save  the  general  business  situation, 
and  especially  to  protect  the  banks,  we  now  turn  to  a  considera- 
tion of  the  direct  financing  of  the  requirements  of  the 
Government  itself.  The  immense  figures  involved  are  a 
matter  of  coramon  knowledge.  They  are  summarized  as  to 
the  classes  of  expenditures  and  as  to  sources  of  receipts  in 
the  tabular  statements  printed  on  page  14.  These  will  be 
found  to  repay  careful  study. 

We  may  now  consider  the  financial  methods  used. 

Inflation  Methods  Used 

It  must  be  frankly  admitted  that  the  expenses  of  the  war 
were  financed  by  inflation  methods.  Not,  however,  the  same 
kind  of  inflation  practiced  by  all  the  Continental  nations  of 
immense  issues  of  bank  notes.  England  did  issue  non-interest 
bearing  circulating  notes — ^the  Currency  (Treasury)  Notes 
already  mentioned — but  the  aggregate  of  ;£356  million  out- 
standing at  the  close  of  1919  looks  very  modest  alongside  of 
the  billions  of  notes  issued,  for  example,  by  the  Bank  of 
France.  The  inflation  was  of  a  more  subtle  kind  but  perhaps 
even  more  potent.  It  was  inflation  by  the  use  of  bank  deposit 
credit. 

Treasury  Bills 

Our  friend  the  Treasury  Bill — successor  to  the  Exchequer 
Bill  of  former  times — ^and  advances  from  the  Bank  of  England 
on  the  credit  of  Ways  and  Means  were  the  principal  agencies 
used  by  the  Government  to  transmute  bank  deposit  credit 

11 


12  ENGLISH  PUBLIC   FINANCE 

into  ships,  aeroplanes,  tanks,  ordnance,  munitions,  food 
and  clothing  for  the  soldiers,  separation  allowances  for  their 
famihes  and  finally  into  a  crushing  defeat  of  the  enemy. 

Taxation 

But  the  entire  dependence  has  not  by  any  means  been 
placed  upon  this  modern  Aladdin's  lamp.  Taxes  have  steadily 
increased.  Where  in  the  first  year  of  the  war  they  amounted 
to  less  than  £200  million,  they  have  since  then  mounted 
year  by  year  until  in  the  fiscal  year  ended  31st  March,  1920, 
they  yielded  nearly  ;f  1,000  milnon  !  The  principle  upon 
which  taxation  has  been  based  has  been  that  the  revenue 
receipts  should  at  least  provide  for  the  ordinary  peace  budget 
and  in  addition  for  the  interest  upon  the  debt  and  for  an 
annual  sum  to  be  apphed  to  its  reduction.  This  ideal  has 
been  fully  reahzed  and  a  good  surplus  in  addition  to  apply 
toward  the  payment  of  the  mihtary  and  other  special  expenses 
caused  by  the  war.  The  provision  of  a  sinking  fund,  while 
the  debt  was  a  growing  one,  may  be  criticized  as  chimerical, 
but  doubtless  it  served  a  useful  purpose  as  a  fund  to  regulate 
the  market  for  the  war  bonds  ;  also  the  fact  that,  at  the  time 
of  incurring  the  debt,  provision  was  made  for  its  ultimate 
payment  probably  had  a  real  value  in  estabhshing  confidence 
in  the  obligations  of  the  nation.  During  the  six  years  under 
review  the  income  from  taxation  and  from  non-tax  revenue, 
other  than  that  from  borrowings,  provided  approximately  for 
35  per  cent,  of  the  first  year's  disbursements,  22  per  cent, 
of  the  second  year's,  over  a  quarter  of  the  third  and 
fourth  year's  disbursements,  over  a  third  of  those  of  the 
fifth  year,  and  for  more  than  80  per  cent,  of  last  fiscal  year's 
expenses. 

Expenditure  of  War  Period 

The  total  expenditure  for  the  six  years  of  the  war  period — • 
that  is,  for  the  fiscal  period  beginning  31st  March,  1914,  and 
ending  31st  March,  1920,  aggregated  ;^1 1,268  million.  Of  this 
war-time  expenditure  ;^3,605  million  was  met  from  normal 


WAR  COSTS  AND   HOW  THEY  WERE   MET  13 

revenue  receipts  ;  £466  million  from  war  contributions, 
receipts  from  sales  of  war  property  and  receipts  from  trading 
undertakings  ;  while  ;f7,196  million  came  from  borrowing,  or 
in  the  proportions  of  36-13  per  cent,  from  revenue  of  all  kinds 
and  63*87  per  cent,  from  borrowing.  Truly  stupendous 
figures  and  a  creditable  result,  and  one  which  gives  great 
confidence  to  the  investor  in  the  nation's  bonds.  All  classes 
of  taxation  have  been  made  to  contribute  to  this  result,  but 
the  great  dependence  of  the  Exchequer  has  been  placed 
upon  the  property  and  income  tax  and  its  modern  running 
mate,  the  excess  profits  duty.  Englishmen  and  their  news- 
paper editors  dehght  in  heckling  and  finding  fault  with 
the  Administration,  as  we  would  say  ;  the  Government,  as 
they  say.  But  to  the  observer  3,000  miles  away,  quietly 
studjnng  the  figures  without  any  other  object  than  to  get  at 
the  facts,  the  results  achieved  seem  little  short  of  marvellous. 
They  could  only  be  obtained  in  a  country  where  patriotism 
runs  so  high  that  the  people  demand  to  be  taxed  and  taxed 
heavily,  as  we  are  assured  was  the  case  in  England  during  the 
course  of  the  war.  The  comparative  tables  on  page  14 
showing  income  and  expenditure  for  the  six  fiscal  years  1914 
to  1920,  inclusive,  summarize  these  data. 

Six  V.  226  Years'  Expenditure 

To  grasp  the  full  significance  of  these  figures  we  may 
advantageously  compare  them  with  the  cost  of  government  for 
a  previous  period.  In  endeavouring  to  make  such  a  com- 
parison we  have  brought  out  the  startUng  fact  to  which 
reference  has  already  been  made  that  the  expenditure  of  the  six 
years  of  the  war  exceeded  the  aggregate  expenditure  of  the 
preceding  two  and  a  quarter  centuries.  The  table  following 
visuaHzes  this  statement.  In  looking  at  the  figures  bear  in 
mind  that  during  the  long  period  of  226  years  there  were  eight 
major  wars,  fought  at  great  expense — expense  so  great  that 
the  thinking  people  of  the  times  were  appalled  thereby. 
Besides  these  major  wars  there  were  many  costly  military 
expeditions,  the  growing  cost  of  civil  government,  and  the 


14 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


GOVERNMENT  INCOME— WORLD  WAR  PERIOD 

31sT  March,   1914,  to  31st  March,  1920 

In  Millions  Sterling 


Years  Ended 
31st  March.                 1915. 

1916. 

1917. 

1918. 

1919. 

1920. 

Total. 

Aver- 
age. 

Per 
Cent. 
Total 
Rev- 
enue. 

Exchequer  balance            .        10 

83 

26 

26 

21 

13 

10 

Tax  Revenue — 
Customs 
Excise 

Estate  duties 
Stamps 

Land,  house,  etc. 
Property    and    income, 
including  super-tax   . 
Excess  profits 

39 

42 

28 

8 

3 

69 

60 
61 
31 

7 
3 

128 

71 

56 

31 

8 

3 

205 
140 

71 

39 

32 

8 

3 

240 
220 

103 

60 

30 

12 

3 

291 
285 

149 
133 
41 
23 
4 

359 
290 

493 

392 

193 

66 

18 

1,292 
935 

82 
65 
32 
11 
3 

215 
156 

12-06 
9-59 
4-72 
1-63 
•45 

31-72 
23-01 

Total  Tax 
Post  Office 
Sundryi 

189 
29 
8 

290 
34 
13 

514  1     613 
34         35 
25          59 

784 
40 
65 

999 

44 

296 

3,389 
216 
466 

565      8318 
36        5-31 
77      11-51 

Total  Revenue 
Borrowing  net 

226   1     337!     673 
410    !  1,167  ,  1,629 

7C7 
1.985 

889 
1682 

1,339 
323 

4,071 
7,196 

678  !  10000 
1.199! 

Total  net  Receipts 

Total  Resources   . 

Revenue — 

%  Receipts 
Borrowing — 

%  Receipts 

636 

646 

35-53 
64-47 

1,604 
1,587 

22-40 
77-59 

2,202 

2,228 

26-02 
73-98 

2,692 

2,718 

26-26 
73-74 

2,671 

2,592 

34-58 
65-42 

1,662 

1,675 

80-56 
19-44 

11,267 

11,277 

36-13 
63-87 

1,878 

•*  £140,000. 

*    Including  war  contributions  from  India,  and  other  overseas  colonies  and  dependencies 
also  receipts  from  sales  of  war  property  and  from  trading  vmdertakings,  etc. 

GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURE— PERIOD  OF  THE 
WORLD  WAR 

31st  March,   1914,  to  31st  March,   1920 

In  Millions  Sterling 


Years  Ended 
31st  March. 

1915. 

1916. 

1917.     1918. 

1919. 

1920.1 

Grand 
Total. 

Aver- 
age. 

Per 
Cent. 

of 
Total. 

Debt — Interest  and  Man- 
agement 

Mihtary  and  other  special 
war  expense 

Civil  Government    . 

Post  Office      . 

22 

437 
78 
26 

60 

1,399 
75 
27 

127        190 

1,974     2  403 
75  '        78 
26          26 

270 

2,198 
85 
26 

332 

1,146 
140 
48 

1,001 

9,557 
531 
179 

166 

1,593 
88 
30 

8-89 

84-81 
4-70 
1-60 

Total  Expenditure 
Exchequer  balance 

663 

83 

1,661 

26 

2,202    2,697    2,679 

26  j        21  1        13 

1,666 

9 

11,268 

1,878 

100-00 

To  be  accounted  for 

646 

1,587     2,228    2,718    2,592 

1,675 

11,277 

'  Division  of  expenses  partly  estimated. 


WAR   COSTS   AND   HOW  THEY   WERE   MET 


15 


ever     present    burden  of  the   public    debt.     Here   are   the 
figures — 

GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURE 
In  Millions  Sterling 


Civil 
Govt. 

Mili- 
tary. 

Debt 
Charge. 

Total. 

2\  Centuries  (1688-1914) 
6  Years  (1915-1920) 

2,873 
710 

4,524 
9,557 

3,547 
1,001 

10.944 
11,268 

Total  (1688-1920)      . 

3,583 

14,081 

4,548 

22,212 

1 

'        ' 

This  is  the  burden  which  German  lust  for  power  and 
territory  placed  on  one  only  of  the  antagonists.  Fortunately 
England  has  the  abihty  to  cope  even  with  such  a  burden,  but 
it  will  require  the  co-operative  work  and  savings  of  more  than 
one  generation  to  liquidate  the  £7,367  miUion  of  increased 
debt  which  the  war  has  left  as  its  aftermath. 


The  Budget,  1 920-1 921 

On  19th  April,  1920,  Mr,  Austen  Chamberlain,  Chancellor 
of  the  Exchequer,  presented  to  Parliament  the  budget  for  the 
cuirent  year  to  end  31st  March,  1921.  In  this  connection  Mr 
Chamberlain  said  :  "  It  is  recognized  on  all  hands  that  the 
present  financial  year  is  of  great  importance  in  the  history  of 
Europe,  and  not  least  for  those  nations  who  emerged  victorious. 
Eighteen  months  have  elapsed  since  the  prehminaries 
of  peace  were  signed.  Though  peace  follows  on  limping 
footsteps  the  time  must  come  when  each  of  us  should  set  his 
house  in  order,  and,  not  content  merely  with  facing  present 
necessities,  lay  broad  and  deep  the  foundations  of  future 
credit  and  prosperity.  This  budget  is,  therefore,  a  critical  one. 
The  paper  in  the  hands  of  members  gives  details  of  the  result 
of  the  past  financial  year." 

The  paper  referred  to  by  Mr.  Chamberlain  is  the  financial 
statement  always  laid  before  the  House  by  the  Chancellor  of 
the  Exchequer  when  opening  the  budget.    The  budget  system 


16  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

of  Great  Britain  is  described  in  a  subsequent  chapter.  As 
we  have  already  surveyed  the  finances  for  the  past  year  we 
may  proceed  at  once  to  consider  the  estimates  for  the  current 
year  to  end  31st  March,  1921. 

These  contemplate  a  total  expenditure  of  £1,184  million 
and  receipts  of  £1,418  milUon.  The  budget  provides  for 
expenses  of  £481  miUion  less  than  the  actual  expenses  of  last 
year  and  for  an  estimated  increase  in  revenue  from  all  sources 
except  borrowing  of  about  £79  million,  or  an  improved  status 
of  the  finances  as  compared  with  the  past  year  of  £560  miUion. 
Therefore,  while  the  financing  of  the  past  year  resulted 
in  a  deficit  of  £326  million,  most  of  which  had  to  be  made  up 
by  new  borrowing,  it  is  expected  that  in  the  current  year 
there  will  be  a  surplus  of  £234  milhon  which  can  be  applied 
to  the  reduction  of  indebtedness. 

In  order  to  accompUsh  this  result  Mr.  Chamberlain  an- 
nounced that  it  would  be  necessary  not  only  to  continue  the 
unpopular  Excess  Profits  Tax  of  40  per  cent.,  but  to  increase 
this  tax  to  60  per  cent.  In  this  connection  Mr.  Chamberlain 
said  :  "  I  base  my  justification  for  the  proposal  on  the  con- 
tinued prevalence  of  temporary  conditions  occasioned  by  the 
war  and  arising  out  of  the  war  creating  a  condition  of  scarcity 
hardly  distinguishable,  in  effect,  from  a  monopoly,  thus  giving 
to  capital  engaged  in  industry  wholly  abnormal  and  often 
extravagant  profits."  Mr.  Chamberlain  then  made  the  fol- 
lowing significant  reference  to  the  proposed  levy  on  war 
capital.  He  said  :  "  The  quahfication  to  which  the  increase  is 
subject  is  this  :  The  House  is  aware  that  a  Select  Committee 
of  this  House  is  now  enquiring  into  the  practicability  of  a 
levy  on  war  increases  of  wealth.  If,  when  they  have  com 
pleted  their  deliberations,  ParUament  should  decide  later 
on  to  impose  such  a  levy,  the  fund  thus  available  would  relieve 
the  pressure  of  the  financial  situation,  enabling  us  to  reverse 
the  decision  to  increase  the  rate  of  Excess  Profits  Duty  to 
60  per  cent.  I  should  therefore  propose  to  submit  to  Parlia- 
ment a  bill  later  in  the  year  to  make  a  levy  on  increases  of  war 
wealth  to  cancel  this  increase  in  the  rate  of  Excess  Profits 


WAR  COSTS  AND  HOW  THEY  WERE  MET  17 

Duty  and  to  collect  Excess  Profits  Duty  for  the  year  at  the 
existing  rate  of  40  per  cent." 

"  The  increased  revenue  to  be  derived  from  this  source  in 
the  current  year  on  the  assumption  that  the  rate  is  60  per  cent, 
will  be  only  £10  million,  raising  the  estimate  of  the  total 
revenue  from  this  source  from  £210  million  to  £220  million. 
More  important  than  the  additional  £10  milhon  actually 
received  will  be  the  further  sums  accruing  but  not  collected 
during  the  present  year,  amounting  to  £65  milhon  next  year  and 
to  a  yet  further  sum  of  £25  milhon  receivable  thereafter.  In 
other  words,  the  addition  to  the  tax  will  produce  £100  million 
in    ah." 

The  other  proposed  changes  in  taxation  were  unimportant 
compared  with  the  one  above  referred  to.  They  comprised 
increased  rates  on  postage  and  for  telegrams  and  possibly  for 
telephone  service,  a  new  tax  on  motor  vehicles  instead  of  the 
existing  taxation,  and  heavy  increases  in  taxation  on  spirits, 
wines,  beer  and  cigars.  Increased  taxes  on  transfers  of  stocks 
are  also  proposed,  while  adjustments  in  the  income  tax  are 
expected  to  result  in  a  reduction  by  £18  milhon.  A  new 
corporation  tax  is  also  proposed.  In  concluding  his  speech, 
Mr,  Chamberlain  said  :  "  These  changes  (in  taxation)  wiU 
produce  in  the  full  year  £198,230,000,  £9,500,000  to  be  drawn 
from  the  Post  Office  and  £189  milhon  derived  as  foUows — • 
from  direct  taxation  £125  milhon,  from  indirect  taxation  £64 
miUion,  For  the  current  year  they  wiU  give  me  a  net  addi- 
tional revenue  of  £76,650,000,  making  a  total  revenue  for  the 
current  year  of  £1,418,300,000.  At  the  close  of  the  year  we 
shall  have  outstanding  assets  of  the  following  amounts  :  loans 
to  the  Dominions,  £119,500,000,  loans  to  allies  and  for  relief, 
£1,767  miUion,  or  taking  them  as  in  former  years  at  half  that 
figure,  £883,500,000  ;  the  remaining  liability  of  India  for  five 
per  cent,  war  loan,  £21  million  ;  vote  of  credit  assets  of  which 
a  portion  may  still  be  required  to  meet  extraordinary  charges, 
£300  milhon  ;  Excess  Profits  Duty  payable  after  the  close  of 
the  current  fiscal  year,  £400  miUion.  In  all,  assets  of  £1,724 
milhon." 

2— (1823) 


18  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

"  In  addition  there  are  reparation  payments  from  our  late 
enemies,  the  amount  and  times  of  which  cannot  yet  be  fixed. 
Whatever  and  whenever  they  are  received  they  will  afford  an 
additional  sum  for  the  reduction  of  debt.  Against  expendi- 
ture, inclusive  of  sinking  fund,  of  £1,184  million  I  provide  a 
revenue  of  £1,418  milhon.  This  gives  me  approximately 
£234  million  for  the  redemption  of  debt  this  year — a  sinking 
fund  equal  to  three  per  cent,  of  the  total  debt.  Of  this  £234 
million  over  £70  milhon  would  be  available  for  the  reduction 
of  the  floating  debt.  As  the  result  of  these  changes  there  is 
every  prospect  that  next  year  there  will  be  available  for  the 
reduction  of  debt  the  sum  of  £300  milhon,  of  which  one-half  at 
any  rate  should  be  free  for  the  floating  debt.  With  the 
advent  of  a  normal  year  when  temporary  and  extraordinary 
receipts  and  charges  have  both  terminated  and  on  the  assump- 
tion that  the  Excess  Profits  Tax  has  also  been  brought  to 
an  end,  there  should  be  available  for  the  sinking  fund  a 
balance  of  not  less  than  £180  million. 

"  After  such  a  war  as  that  in  which  we  have  been  engaged 
and  after  gigantic  financial  sacrifices,  this  is  a  position  of 
unexampled  and  unequalled  strength.  It  is  true  that  to 
attain  it  we  are  obliged  to  impose  fresh  taxation  and  to  call 
for  further  sacrifices.  That  may  not  bring  popularity  to 
the  Government  or  to  the  Minister.  I  am  proud  to  say  that 
we  have  not  sought  it.  Our  object  has  been  to  rise  to  the 
level  of  our  great  responsibilities,  so  that  when  we  surrender 
the  seals  of  office  we  may  leave  to  our  successors  an  ample 
revenue  and  to  our  country  a  national  credit  second  to  none." 

During  the  course  of  the  debate  which  followed  the 
presentation  of  the  budget  one  of  the  members  made  the 
statement  that  two  such  budgets  would  destroy  the  Empire, 
to  which  Mr.  Chamberlain  replied,  "  I  will  not  stop  to  retort 
that  twenty  such  budgets  would  redeem  the  whole  of  our 
debt." 


CHAPTER  IV 

THE  WAR   DEBT 
(1914-1920) 

To  return  to  the  subject  of  the  debt.  The  method  pursued 
was,  in  the  first  instance,  to  secure  advances  from  the  Bank 
of  England  by  book  credits — called  "  Ways  and  Means 
Advances  " — or  to  sell  Treasury  Bills.  The  sales  of  Treasury 
Bills  have  far  exceeded  the  advances.  They  have  been  sold 
to  mature  at  various  periods  ranging  from  three  months 
to  a  year.  At  first  the  Government  asked  for  tenders,  then 
it  put  them  on  sale  over  the  counter.  "When  tenders  were 
asked,  the  bidder  stated  the  rates  of  interest  he  was  willing  to 
accept.  As  a  rule  it  has  apparently  been  found  more  satis- 
factory to  offer  the  bills  at  a  fixed  rate  of  discount.  This 
discount  rate  has  varied  with  the  market  rates  for  money. 
The  rates  offered  from  time  to  time  may  be  found  by 
consulting  the  table  printed  on  page  181. 

The  First  War  Loans 

The  second  step  in  the  process  of  debt  financing  was  to 
make,  at  convenient  intervals,  issues  of  long  dated  bonds 
from  the  proceeds  of  which  the  Treasury  Bills  outstanding 
were  reduced  or  retired,  new  issues  being  made  again  as  fimds 
were  needed. 

It  would  be  tedious  to  burden  our  pages  with  a  detailed 
description  of  each  series  of  bonds  issued.  The  issues  now 
outstanding  will  be  found  described  in  the  National  Debt 
Statement  to  be  found  on  page  181.  However,  it  will  be  quite 
worth  while  and  of  interest  to  note  how  the  more  important 
loans  were  taken  by  the  pubHc.  The  first  of  these  loans  was 
for  ;^350  milhon  in  3|  per  cents.  It  was  offered  in  November, 
1914,  at  95  and  was  subscribed  by  nearly  100,000  applicants. 
The  next  loan  was  offered  as  4|  per  cents,  at  par  in  June 

19 


20  ENGLISH   PUBLIC    FINANCE 

and  July,  1915,  and  £570  million  were  taken  by  over  550,000 
subscribers  asking  for  an  average  of  about  £1,000  each,  while 
1,330,000  subscribers  bid  through  the  post  offices  for 
£35,600,000  bonds,  an  average  of  £26  6s.  each.  Then  there 
was  the  Anglo-French  5  per  cent,  loan  placed  in  the  United 
States  in  October,  1915,  of  which  England's  share  was  £51 
million. 

The  Foreign  Securities  Mobilization 

Then  came,  in  December,  1915,  the  scheme  for  the  mobiliza- 
tion of  the  foreign  investment  holdings  of  the  British  people 
and  their  use  to  stabihze  the  American  exchanges  and  to 
create  credits  in  America  against  which  purchases  of  munitions 
and  other  necessary  supplies  could  be  financed.  The  holders 
of  such  securities  were  asked  to  sell  them  or  lend  them  to  the 
Treasury  for  sale  in  America  or  for  use  as  collateral  behind 
issues  of  dollar  bonds  to  be  sold  in  the  United  States.  The 
owners  of  the  securities  used  as  collateral  received  a  certificate 
entithng  them  to  the  interest  which  the  loaned  securities 
5nelded  plus  a  payment  at  the  rate  of  one-half  per  cent,  per 
annum.  The  Government  reserved  the  right  of  purchase, 
in  which  event  the  owner  was  to  receive  a  fair  market  rate 
for  his  bonds  or  stocks.  The  response  to  this  request  was 
spontaneous  and  resulted  by  the  end  of  1916  in  the  acquisi- 
tion by  the  Treasury  of  American  stocks  and  bonds  of  a  par 
value  in  sterhng  of  £465  million,  £118  milhon  by  purchase 
and  £347  miUion  on  deposit.  The  entrance  of  the  United 
States  into  the  field  in  April,  1917,  as  an  active  participant  in 
the  conflict  put  an  end  to  the  necessity  for  further  important 
financing  of  this  kind.  The  result  of  the  operations  of  the 
British  Treasury  was  to  maintain  New  York  exchange  at 
practically  a  uniform  rate  of  $4.76xV  from  January,  1916, 
until  21st  March,  1919,  when  the  control  was  removed. 
Similar  operations  were  carried  out  for  the  stabiUzation  of  the 
Dutch  and  Scandinavian  exchanges.  For  the  entire  period 
the  total  securities  purchased  amounted  to  £241  milhon,  of 
which  amount  £46,600,000  were  purchased  by  the  Bank  of 
England   during   1915,    prior    to  the    inauguration     of  the 


THE  WAR  DEBT  21 

mobilization  scheme.  The  deposits  on  loan  amounted  to  £41A 
million.  The  latter  item  included  a  special  deposit  of  £8 
million  by  the  Canadian  Pacific.  Thus  the  total  amount  of 
securities  dealt  with  was  £655  million. 

The  War  Loans  in  1917 

In  January  and  February,  1917,  the  4  per  cent,  and  5  per 
cent.  War  Loan  met  with  an  enthusiastic  reception,  about 
£1,000  million  being  sold  for  cash.  This  time  apphcants 
through  the  Bank,  numbering  1,089,000,  took  over  £819 
milhon  bonds  ;  about  one  milHon  applicants  through  the 
post  office  took  nearly  £31  miUion,  while  it  is  estimated  that 
over  four  miUion  members  of  war  savings  clubs  participated  in 
purchases  by  such  clubs  of  around  £20  milhon  bonds.  Holders 
of  about  £131  million  Treasury  Bills  exchanged  them  for  these 
bonds. 

War  Savings  Associations 

The  War  Savings  Associations  were  one  of  the  finest  achieve- 
ments of  the  war  finance.  The  general  idea  was  adopted  in 
our  own  country  after  we  came  into  the  war  in  the  form  of 
our  W.S.S.  with  which  we  are  all  famihar.  In  England  there 
were  many  group  purchasers,  neighbourhood  groups,  servant 
groups,  tradesmen  groups  and  the  like.  Sometimes  they 
pooled  their  purchases  and  offered  prizes  of  various  kinds. 
Then  when  a  permanent  war  loan  came  out  these  groups  used 
their  organizations  to  promote  the  sales  of  bonds  among  their 
numbers. 

It  is  of  interest  to  note  that  the  National  War  Savings 
Committee  was  inaugurated  by  the  British  Treasury  in 
February,  1916,  on  the  advice  of  a  Committee  presided  over 
by  Lord  Montagu  of  Beaulieu.   Its  immediate  functions  were  : 

(1)  To  educate  the  pubUc  as  to  the  necessity  for  saving 
and  for  the  reduction  of  unnecessary  consumption  by  all 
classes,  and  (2)  to  provide  facilities  for  the  small  investor  to 
invest  in  State  securities. 


22  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

War  Savings  Certificates  were  immediately  issued,  and  the 
National  Committee  proceeded  to  set  up  "  War  Savings 
Associations."  Decentralization  being  found  essential  to  the 
scheme,  Local  Savings  Committees  were  organized  throughout 
Great  Britain,  a  democratic  basis  therefore  being  imparted 
to  the  scheme  from  the  outset. 

By  the  date  of  the  armistice  in  November,  1918,  there 
were  some  1,800  local  committees,  14,000  ofi&cial  agents  and 
branches,  and  40,000  associations  numbering  not  less  than 
5  miUion  members.  More  than  250  million  of  War  Savings 
Certificates  had  been  sold,  and  the  sum  of  nearly  ;^201  million 
had  been  invested  in  the  certificates  by  the  public. 

From  that  date  to  January,  1920,  nearly  ;^95|  million 
sterling  had  been  subscribed  in  savings  certificates.  The 
average  number  of  certificates  sold  monthly  had  been  9 
million,  while  the  withdrawals  were  approximately  only  10 
per  cent,  of  the  total  issue.  The  amount  outstanding  on 
1st  January,  1920,  was  i2<ol  million. 

At  a  great  gathering  in  London  on  15th  January,  1920,  Mr. 
Austen  Chamberlain,  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  stated 
that  notwithstanding  the  success  in  popularizing  the  new 
forms  of  investment,  the  old  forms  had  risen  to  higher  figures 
than  they  ever  attained  before.  He  said  that  before  the  war, 
the  deposits  in  the  Post  Of&ce  and  the  Trustee  Savings  Banks 
were  something  under  £300  million,  while  by  the  end  of 
October,  1919,  they  had  risen  to  nearly  £800^  million. 

Sir  Robert  Kindersley,  director  of  the  Bank  of  England, 

to  whom,  as  Chairman  of  the  National  Savings  Committee,  so 

much  of  the  success  of  the  whole  movement  is  due,  told  at  this 

same  meeting  how  the  army  of  voluntary  workers  for  national 

savings  enhsted  by  the  Government  from  1916  onwards  had 

captured  the  imagination  of  the  great  mass  of  the  people.     He 

dwelt  upon  that  innate    "  spirit  of  adventure  "    which  has 

made  the  British  Empire  what  it  is  to-day,  and  which  promised 

to  make  the  movement  as  big  a  success  in  peace  as  in  war 

^  This  item  includes  deposits,  the  value  of  securities  held  by  stock- 
holders in  the  Post  Office  and  Trustee  Savings  Banks  and  the  amount 
of  War  Savings  Certificates  outstanding. 


THE  WAR  DEBT  23 

time  ;  and  emphasized  the  fact  that,  out  of  nearly  400  million 
War  Savings  Certificates  sold  since  the  inauguration  of  the 
movement,  124  million  had  been  disposed  of  since  the  armistice. 

As  far  back  as  the  middle  of  1917,  the  Commissioners  of  the 
British  Treasury  appointed  a  committee  to  consider  facilities 
to  be  given  to  the  small  investor  after  the  war  and,  in  view  of 
the  genuine  success  which  the  movement  had  achieved,  this 
committee  recommended  the  permanent  continuance  of  the 
War  Savings  Certificate,  having  regard  to  the  main  fact  that 
the  habit  of  saving  had  been  formed  by  "  numerous  persons  of 
all  classes  who  had  not  previously  acquired  it," 

In  November,  1918,  the  Committee  on  Financial  Facilities 
reported  that  it  was  enormously  impressed  by  the  great 
increase  in  the  number  of  small  investors,  and  that  the  policy 
which  had  proved  so  successful  during  the  war  must  be 
continued  at  all  costs.  It  was  decided  to  extend  the  "hfe" 
of  a  certificate  from  five  years  to  ten,  and  that  it  could  be 
cashed  at  any  time  during  that  period. 

Particular  attention  has  been  paid,  too,  to  the  educational 
value  of  the  movement.  Largely  owing  to  the  good  work  of 
the  educational  authorities  and  of  thousands  of  the  teachers 
themselves,  some  12,500  School  Associations  were  set  up 
during  the  war. 

In  October,  1919,  the  Board  of  Education  circularized  all 
the  local  education  authorities,  urging  upon  them  the  continu- 
ance of  the  war  savings  movement  in  schools.  To  this  appeal 
an  absolutely  unanimous  affirmative  was  given,  and  the 
National  Union  of  Teachers  was  requested  to  render  support 
to  the  National  Savings  Committee.  This  the  teachers  are 
accordingly  doing  with  all  the  means  at  their  disposal,  and 
with  absolutely  unconquerable  optimism. 

As  Sir  Robert  Kindersley  summed  it  up  : 

"  First  of  all  we  had  the  impetus  of  the  war,  the  desire  on 
the  part  of  everybody  to  try  and  help  to  win  the  war — ^that 
was  the  first  advantage  that  we  had.  But  we  should  have 
absolutely  failed  in  this  movement  if  we  had  simply  set  out  as 
a  pure  collecting  agency  of  money  for  the  State.    We  had  to 


24  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

have  behind  us  a  gospel.  In  fine,  it  was  from  the  outset  a 
gigantic  effort  in  unselfishness  on  the  part  of  an  entire  com- 
munity, which  has  seldom,  if  ever,  been  equalled  in  the  history 
of  humankind." 

National  War  Bonds — Continuous  Offering 

In  the  latter  part  of  1917  and  during  1918  and  1919  the 
Treasury  tried  the  interesting  experiment  of  abandoning 
spectacular  periodical  offerings  and,  instead,  of  putting 
on  continuous  sale  over  the  country  the  National  War  Bonds. 
The  idea  was  to  feed  the  bonds  out  from  day  to  day  and 
thus  to  have  a  steady  flow  of  money  into  the  Treasury  of, 
say,  £25  million  a  week.  The  bonds  were  issued  as  fives 
subject  to  taxation,  or  as  fours  "  income  tax  compounded." 
While  the  expected  goal  was  not  fully  reached,  yet  the  sales 
were  very  substantial.  The  amount  of  the  issue  outstanding  at 
the  close  of  1919  was  one  and  a  half  thousand  million  sterling. 

Victory  Loan  of  1919 

In  June  and  July,  1919,  the  Treasury  offered  what  was 
called  the  "  Victory  Loan  "  at  85,  and  in  conjunction  there- 
with the  "  Funding  Loan  "  at  80.  These  loans  bore  4  per 
cent,  interest.     Some  £776  million  bonds  were  sold. 

Summary 

The  funded  and  unfunded  debt  as  on  31st  December,  1919, 
when  the  debt  had  reached  its  maximum,  was  £8,078  million 
held  by  over  17,000,000  investors.  This  compared  with  a  debt 
of  £711  million  on  1st  August,  1914,  held  by  about  345,000 
investors.  At  the  close  of  the  fiscal  year,  31st  March,  1920, 
the  debt  stood  at  £7,825  million,  a  beginning  having  at  last 
been  made  toward  its  reduction. 

In  the  following  table  the  debt  is  summarized  according 
to  dates  of  maturity.  It  will  be  noted  that  about  one-fifth 
(if  the  debt  matures  within  one  year  and  about  28  per  cent, 
in  addition  within  five  years  ;  making  nearly  50  per  cent. 
maturing  within  five  years. 


THE  WAR  DEBT 


25 


NATIONAL  DEBT. 
Funded  and  Unfunded  as  on  31st  December,  1919. 


Milhon 
i 

Due  Within  One  Year — 

Ways  and  Means  Advances 

243,2 

Treasury  Bills 

1,106,6 

Exchequer  Bonds 

160,3 

Anglo-French  Loan   . 

51,4 

Victory  Bonds 

5,0 

Due  Within  One  to  Five  Years — 

Exchequer  Bonds 

146,4 

Victory  Bonds 

20,1 

National  War  Bonds 

619,0 

Annuities           .... 

8,2 

War  Savings  Certificates     . 

267,3 

Debt  in  United  States 

48,5 

Debt  Due  to  United  States  Governme 

nt     867.4 

Other  debt  due  to  war — due  Foreigi 

1 

Nations  and  to  Dominions 

329,8 

Due  Within  Five  to  Seventy  Years 



Exchequer  Bonds 

16,6 

Victory  Bonds 

334.4 

National  War  Bonds 

889,8 

War  Loans        .... 

2,122,6 

Debt  in  United  States 
Funding  Loan 

60.0 

409,1 

Perpetual — 

Annuities  for  life  and  term  of  years 

11.8 

Consols     ..... 

301,4 

Debts  due  to  Bank  of  England   . 

11,0 

Debts  due  to  Bank  of  Ireland 

2,6 

Miscellaneous — 

Other  Capital  Liabilities 

Total 


Total. 


Per 

Cent,  of 

Total. 


1.566,5  19-39 


2,306,7         28-56 


3,832,5 


326.8 


47-44 


4-04 


46.2 


•57 


8,078,7        100-00 


The  outstanding  Treasury  Notes,  amounting  on  SlstDecember, 
1919,  to  £356  million,  must  not  be  overlooked  in  considering 
the  debt.  However,  as  to  the  extent  of  £32,500,000  they 
are  covered  by  gold  and  Bank  of  England  notes  and  for 


26  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

the  rest  by  Government  interest -bearing  securities  which  are 
included  in  the  debt  statement,  they  need  not  be  added  to 
the  above  total  of  £8,078  million  in  order  to  determine  the 
aggregate  debt. 

Proposed  Debt  Reduction 

The  British  Government  are  fully  alive  to  the  necessity 
for  reducing  the  debt  as  promptly  as  possible  and  particularly 
for  making  provision  for  the  debt  having  early  maturities. 
We  have  akeady  noted  in  connection  with  the  discussion  of 
the  budget  for  the  current  fiscal  year  that  during  this  year  the 
Government  purpose  to  reduce  the  indebtedness  by  the  sum 
of  £234  million.  The  London  Joint  City  and  Midland  Bank  in 
their  monthly  review  for  April,  1920.  comment  as  follows 
on  this  matter — 

"If  expenditure  and  revenue  for  the  current  year  fulfil 
budget  estimates  the  surplus  will  be  about  £234  million.  Out 
of  this  surplus  the  Chancellor  estimates  that  about  £160 
millions  will  be  required  for  the  Victory  Loan  Sinking  Fund, 
for  cancellation  of  debt  through  revenue  payments  in  scrip,  for 
the  Depreciation  Fund  on  the  1917  War  Loans  and  for 
provision  to  meet  old  debt  (mainly  external)  maturing  in 
1920-1921.  The  balance  of  £74  milUon  is  to  be  applied  to 
reduction  of  floating  debt.  In  arriving  at  this  figure  the 
Chancellor  has  apparently  not  taken  into  consideration  repay- 
ments of  £36|  million  on  account  of  Civil  Contingencies  due 
before  30th  September,  1920,  or  the  proceeds  of  sales  of 
Savings  Certificates  during  the  financial  year .  We  show  in  the 
appended  statement  that  if  receipts  on  account  of  Civil 
Contingencies  and  Savings  Certificates  are  included,  there  may 
be  a  balance  of  £115  million  available  for  the  repayment  of 
Treasury  Bills  and  Ways  and  Means  Advances,  after  making 
provision  for  the  repayment  of  £25  million  of  Exchequer 
Bonds  in  December  next. 

"  If  the  following  estimates  prove  to  be  correct  the  amount 
of  debt  outstanding  on  31st  March,  1921,  will  be  about 
£7,565  million." 


THE  WAR  DEBT 


27 


ESTIMATED  CHANGES  IN  DEBT,   1920-21 


(000  omitted). 


Cr 


Budget  Surplus,  1920-21, 
on  1919-20  basis  of 
taxation  .  .  ^^157,548 

Add  estimated  revenue 
in  1920-21  from  new 
taxes 

Civil  Contingencies 
Fund  —  Repayments 
due  before  30th  Sep- 
tember, 1920      . 

Sales  of  Savings  Certifi- 
cates, based  upon  net 
proceeds  3  months  to 
31st  March.  1920 


76,650 


36,490 


29,840 


;^300,528 


Dr 


Victory     Loan     Sinking 

Fund 
Cancellations       through 

Death  Duty  Payments  : 


;^3,840 


Victory  Loan 

10,000 

Other  War  Loans   . 

5,000 

Cancellations        through 

Excess    Profits    Duty 

payments 

60,000 

4%  and  5%  War  Loan 

Depreciation  Fund 

31,920 

Repayment  of  Old  Debt 

(mainly  external  ^) 

49,240 

160,000 

5%     Exchequer     Bonds 

due  1st  Dec  ,1920      . 

25378 

Available  for  repayment 
of  Treasury  Bills 
and/or  Ways  and 
Means  Advances 


185,378 


115,150 

/300,528 


^  Presumably  the  Anglo-French  Loan.    H.  E.  F. 


Refunding  Operations 

The  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  announced  on  28th  April 
his  intention  to  place  on  sale,  as  on  3rd  May,  a  new  series  of 
Treasury  Bonds  with  the  avowed  object  of  reducing  the 
floating  debt  of  early  maturity.  The  amount  of  bonds  to  be 
issued  is  unlimited  and  they  will  be  on  sale  at  the  Bank  of 
England  until  further  notice.  The  principal  and  interest  of 
the  bonds  are  chargeable  on  the  Consohdated  Fund.  The 
bonds  will  be  repayable  on  1st  May,  1935,  or  on  1st  May 
in  any  one  of  the  years  1925  to  1934,  inclusive,  at  the  option 
of  the  Government  or  of  holders  of  the  bonds,  on  notice 
having  been  given  by  the  Treasury  or  the  holders  during 
the  month  of  April  in  the  year  preceding  that  in  which  such 
repayment  is  to  take  place. 


28  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

A  novel  plan  is  proposed  in  regard  to  payment  of  interest. 
We  quote  from  the  official  circular — 

"  The  bonds  will  carry  interest  at  the  rate  of  5  per  cent, 
per  annum  payable  half-yearly  on  1st  May  and  1st  November 
and,  subject  to  the  conditions  stated  below,  will  carry  addi- 
tional interest  payable  during  the  period  ending  1st  May, 
1925,  as  follows  :  If  and  when  during  any  half-year  ended  1st 
May  or  1st  November,  the  Treasury  Bills  issued  to  the  public 
were  sold  to  them  at  an  average  rate  of  discount  (as  certified  by 
the  Bank  of  England)  exceeding  5 J  per  cent,  and  under  6^  per 
cent,  per  annum,  additional  interest  will  be  payable  on  the 
interest  date  next  succeeding  such  1st  May  or  1st  November  at 
the  rate  of  1  per  cent,  per  annum.  If  and  when  such  average 
rate  of  discount  was  6^  per  cent,  per  annum  or  over  additional 
interest  will  be  payable  at  the  rate  of  2  per  cent,  per  annum. 

"  The  first  interest  payment,  payable  1st  November,  1920, 
will  represent  in  the  case  of  each  bond  interest  to  that  date 
from  the  date  on  which  the  application  was  lodged  and 
pa5niient  made  for  the  bond,  and  will  include  additional 
interest  at  the  rate  of  2  per  cent,  per  annum. 

"  An  announcement  will  be  published  in  the  London  Gazette 
on  or  about  the  2nd  November,  1920,  and  thereafter  half- 
yearly  until  the  2nd  November,  1924,  of  the  rate  at  which 
Additional  Interest  (if  any)  will  be  payable  on  the  next 
succeeding  interest  date." 

In  the  opinion  of  the  Chancellor,  the  novel  feature  in  regard 
to  the  payment  of  interest  will  probably  protect  holders 
against  depreciation  in  market  values  when  short-term  money 
rates  are  high  and  also  prevent  the  new  issue  of  bonds  from 
causing  further  depreciation  of  market  values  of  the  older 
issues.  The  maximum  possible  average  yield  from  the  new 
bonds  if  held  until  1935  would  be  £5  17s.  4d.  per  cent.  At  the 
time  of  issue  3|  per  cent.  War  Loan  was  selhng  to  yield 
£7  3s.  7d.  per  cent.  ;  A\  per  cent.  War  Loan  £6  7s.  6d.  per  cent. 
and  5  per  cent.  War  Loan,  £6  5s.  Id.  per  cent.,  therefore  the 
success  of  the  new  issue  was  considered  problematical.  How- 
ever, the  Government  is  so  fully  alive  to  the  importance  of 


THE   WAR   DEBT 


29 


liquidating  or  funding  the  floating  debt  and  the  debt  of  early 
maturity  that  any  modification  of  present  plans  necessary 
to  insure  this  result  may  confidently  be  expected. 

Credits  to  Debt  Account 

The  debt  on  31st  March,  1920,  of  about  £7,973  milHon 
was  offset  by  advances  of  £1,851  million  ;  say,  to  the  Domin- 
ions of  £120  million  and  to  allied  governments  of  £1,731 
million. 

The  following  itemized  statement  is  taken  from  the  financial 
statement  already  referred  to  laid  before  the  House  upon 
the  opening  of  the  budget — 

LOANS  TO  DOMINIONS  AND  ALLIES. 
31sT  March,   1920. 
(00,000  omitted.) 
Obligations  of  Dominions — 


Australia     ..... 

.          ;^51.6 

New  Zealand        .... 

29,6 

Canada         ..... 

19.4 

South  Africa         .... 

15,8 

Other  Dominions  and  Colonies 

3,1 

£119,5 

BLIGATIONS    OF    ALLIES 

Russia          ..... 

.     ;^568,0 

France         ..... 

514,8 

Italy 

.       455,5 

Belgium  (a)  War 

92,0 

{b)   Reconstruction 

5,3 

Serbia           ..... 

20,9 

Portugal,  Roumania,  Greece  and  other 

AlHes         66,6 

Relief  Loans          .... 

8,0 

;^1.731,1 

;^1,850,6 

Further  advances  of  £36  miUion  provided  for  in  the  estimates 
1920-21  will  raise  this  total  by  31st  March,  1921,  to 
approximately  £1,886  million. 

Mr.    Chamberlain    in    his    budget    speech    estimated   the 


30  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

advances  to  the  allies  as  probably  realizable  at  about  50  per 
cent,  of  their  face  value.  This  would  afford  an  offset  of  about 
£1,000  million  against  the  gross  debt. 

It  is  understood  that  no  interest  has  been  charged  on  the 
pre-armistice  debt  of  Belgium,  Serbia  and  Montenegro.  It  is 
understood  that  in  the  case  of  Belgium,  the  French,  American 
and  British  Governments  have  agreed  to  accept  German 
bonds  for  the  amount  of  Belgian  indebtedness.  In  other 
cases  interest  is  calculated  either  at  5  per  cent,  or  at  bank 
rate  and  is  added  to  the  principal  of  the  loans  outstanding,  so 
that  no  payments  of  interest  on  pre-armistice  debt  have  been 
received  by  the  Exchequer  except  in  respect  of  a  single  trans- 
action where  special  arrangements  were  made.  Negotiations 
as  to  the  future  treatment  of  the  debts  of  the  allied  and 
associated  governments  are  proceeding  and  the  Government 
have  expressed  their  wiUingness  to  extend  to  their  debtors 
similar  treatment  to  that  which  may  be  arranged  in  respect 
of  their  own  debt. 

The  Comparative  Burden  of  the  Debt 

Assuming,  then,  about  £1,000  million  to  be  reahzable 
from  debtor  nations  and  the  Dominions,  the  net  indebted- 
ness of  the  nation  on  31st  March,  1920,  may  be  placed  at 
£7,000  milhon  as  against  national  wealth  estimated  at  perhaps 
£24,000  million  ;  a  ratio  of  about  30  per  cent,  net  debt  to 
national  wealth.  The  debt  charge  of,  say,  £360  milhon 
compares  with  estimated  national  income  of  about  £3,600 
million.  Therefore  the  debt  of  to-day  bears  about  the  same 
relation  to  wealth  that  the  debt  at  the  close  of  the  Napoleonic 
wars  bore  to  the  estimated  wealth  at  that  time.  The  interest 
charge  now,  at  10  per  cent,  of  the  income,  compares  with 
8  per  cent,  in  1817. 

In  the  table  printed  on  the  opposite  page  further  interesting 
comparisons  are  made  with  conditions  at  the  conclusion  of 
the  Boer  War  and  on  1st  August,  1914,  just  before  the  recent 
war  began. 


Q 

W 

« 

<: 

H 

fi( 

< 

:s 

o 

H 

CJ 

PQ 

W 
Q 

Q 
O 

O 

1— ( 

'^ 

Ph 

w 

H 

M 

5^ 

fii 

<1 

U) 

H 

«  « 

O 

W 

C^ 

ffi^ 

H 

hH 

« 

P 

o 

p^ 

73° 

CO 

CD 

O 

■0 

3 

.£!>? 

<A° 

o 

CO 

o 

o 

> 

V*}-* 

eo 

eo 

u> 

z 
o 

8 

•c 

eo 

u 

S 

•*0 

in 

-4n 

O 

.■♦ 

i« 

•f 

i^ 

J  °  H  c.  i     • 

u  Co! 

<  ==  5  m  t1 « 

H  W  3  2  ^  •< 
O  0.  H  J  -  W    - 

o.«.ti 

'^■"f 

■"I- 

•* 

m 

eo 

o"^ 

VH?^ 

s 

o 

S 

■<2 

N 

N 

2 

-e   :s 

"f 

CO 

BO       a 

<b 

(U.u.       Q 

eo 

» 

t^ 

UH.— ~ 

d 

i« 

M 

^ 

■< 

int;    •< 

t>. 

CO 

r^ 

o 

s 

do 

eo 

u  >■ 

Vig 

o 

s 

O 

><< 

rs 

,_: 

05 
0) 

00 

§ 

O   c4 

<2 

<^-_ 

M 

o" 

Per 
Cent. 

t     to 

"8 

o 

00 

CO 

9 

o 
o 

.t^ 

eo 

o 

CO 

«sj— 

o 

o 

l> 

6-S 
<3 

**jjco 

"^00~ 

s 

i 

^M 

eo 

o 

in 

0» 

00 

N 

■<f 

r* 

o-;3 

o 

o 

o 

o 

•<  !E 

v*jO 

lO 

U5 

o 

z:- 

<2 

^Tf 

t^ 

_M_ 

CO 

eo 

•  *> 

5 

00 

eo 

t^ 

in 

lll^ 

•"T 

CO 

CD 

^ 

CO 

■^ 

eb 

% 

CO 

eo 

i'   Am 

&6^ 

o 

o> 

in 

in 

V^IO 

r» 

41 

o 

"oo~ 

00 

Q 

"^s 

S 

t^ 

i 

^§i 

o> 

d 

1/5 

M 

B 

v,jU5 

§ 

s 

s 

8 

§ 

§ 

§ 

H 
^ 

<2 

eo" 

■*" 

•"a"" 
M 

e- js  9 

r^ 

d 

CO 

CD 

<2^-2 

■* 

■w 

■X" 

^ 

rs 

eo 

Oi 

s 

2 

a> 

s 

§ 

d 

ja" 

3 

o" 

n 

bo 

Q 

•—1 

rt 

3 
< 

Q 

£ 

s 

H 

O) 

to 

tn 

S 

, 

IN 

eo 

O 

O 

t3 

_ 

S 

^ 

M 

rd 

P< 

c 

ij 

. 

," 

bn 

1 

O 

3 

[! 

a 

U 

S 

n] 

o 

> 

o 

ca 

(S 

o        , 


•3    3 

^        3      o 
2      (2    js 


a      S 


an  ■- 

a  a    o 

■M  d  «i, 

C3  O    -• 

I" «, 

o5  ® 

-sl  ^ 

0,13     00 
!<■"   <tJ 

*  3     " 
?  2    J3 

^      'C  is" 


-J3     « 

4;  T3      (W 


III 

OH    8 


V    (1 


32  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

The  great  progress  in  the  past  century  in  science  and  in 
its  application  to  the  arts  enabled  Great  Britain  to  expand 
her  business  and  increase  her  capital  at  such  a  rate  as  to 
reduce  steadily  the  burden  of  the  debt  in  comparison  with 
national  income  and  resources. 

It  is  impossible  now  to  determine  just  what  the  future  may 
have  in  store  to  mitigate  the  present  day  burden.  The  won- 
derful developments  in  air  navigation  during  the  war  and  the 
great  importance  which  the  chemical  industries  assumed 
during  that  period  may  afford  a  hint  of  surprises  in  store  which 
will  assist  in  lightening  to-day's  burden.  Potent  factors  in 
assisting  Great  Britain  to  create  new  assets  to  balance  her 
war  liabilities  will  be  the  closer  knitting  together  of  the 
Empire,  the  further  colonial  development  in  Mesopotamia 
and  in  Africa,  and  redoubled  efforts  to  extend  her  commerce, 
especially  in  Russia  and  the  Far  East.  Lessons  in  efficiency 
taught  by  the  war,  and  a  larger  use  of  machinery,  doubtless  will 
also  play  an  important  part  in  the  developments  of  the  future. 


CHAPTER   V 

HOW   THE    BANKS    HELPED    FINANCE    THE    WAR 
(1914-1920) 

For  the  benefit  of  those  who  are  not  familiar  with  banking 
operations  in  England  and  the  United  States  it  may  be 
explained  that,  as  a  usual  thing,  every  loan  made  by  a  bank 
results  in  an  increase  in  the  deposits  of  the  bank  or  of  some 
other  bank.  If  a  merchant  or  manufacturer  or  other  business 
man  borrows  at  his  bank  he  usually  has  the  amount  of  the 
loan  credited  to  his  account .  The  result  is  that  an  increase  in 
bank  loans  is  nearly  always  accompanied  by  an  increase  in 
bank  deposits.  Therefore,  an  increase  in  the  deposits  of  a 
bank  is  not  necessarily,  as  is  often  thought,  an  index  of  the 
increasing  wealth  of  a  community,  but  often  merely  of  in- 
creasing business  activity,  or  simply  of  credit  expansion.  If 
the  increase  in  loans  and  consequent  increase  in  deposits  is 
brought  about  by  unproductive  borrowing,  this  gain  in  deposits 
may  be  a  sign  of  financial  weakness  rather  than  an  indication 
of  growing  wealth. 

The  war  financing  in  England  and  in  America  was  effected 
by  the  use  on  a  large  scale  of  this  familiar  process  of  every- 
day banking.  Each  loan  issued  by  the  nation  increased  the 
loans  as  well  as  the  deposits  of  the  banks.  This  was  due  in 
large  part  to  the  fact  that  in  many  instances  the  purchasers 
of  government  obligations  borrowed  from  their  banks  in  order 
to  obtain  the  funds  with  which  to  pay  the  Government. 
These  loans  created  deposits  against  which  cheques  were 
drawn  to  the  order  of  the  Government — ^that  is,  in  England,  to 
the  order  of  the  Bank  of  England.  The  actual  payment 
might  have  been  to  the  order  of  one  of  the  joint -stock  banks, 
but  ultimately  the  money  would  reach  the  Exchequer  through 
the  Bank  of  England.  The  Government  would  then  draw 
upon  this  deposit  to  pay  its  expenses  for  mimitions,  for  food 

33 

3— (1823) 


34  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

and  clothing  for  the  enlisted  men,  and  for  the  hundred  and 
one  other  needs  of  a  nation  in  a  time  of  war. 

Bank  Reserves  v.  Credits 

The  extent  to  which  a  bank  can  extend  credits  to  its 
customers  is  determined  by  its  reserves,  in  England  often 
called  cash  balances.  As  a  result  of  long  experience  bankers 
have  found  that  on  the  average  only  a  certain  percentage  of 
their  deposits  is  drawn  upon  ;  the  balance  remains  more  or 
less  as  a  fixed  deposit.  This  balance  can  be  safely  loaned  to 
the  business  community,  but  a  reserve  in  the  form  of  actual 
money  or  its  equivalent  must  always  be  held,  out  of  which  the 
cheques  of  depositors  can  be  promptly  met. 

Such  a  fund  is  a  prime  essential  of  solvency.  In  England 
the  banks  have  established  the  custom,  instead  of  holding  all 
of  this  reserve  in  actual  money,  of  keeping  the  greater  part 
in  the  form  of  a  deposit  with  the  Bank  of  England.  In  the 
United  States  the  member  banks  of  the  Federal  Reserve 
System,  which  comprise  all  the  National  Banks  and  most  of 
the  large  State  banks,  are  required  to  carry  their  legal  reserve 
with  the  Federal  Reserve  Banks.  The  experience  of  banks  as 
to  the  amount  of  reserve  which  must  be  held  varies  with  their 
location,  the  nature  of  the  business  done  by  their  clients,  the 
season  of  the  year  and  other  conditions.  In  general,  it  is  found 
that  for  commercial  banks  (other  than  central  banks  of  issue) 
a  reserve  of  from  10  to  20  per  cent,  of  deposits  is  ample 
in  normal  times.  That  is,  if  the  English  banks  have  on  hand 
in  gold.  Bank  of  England  notes,  and/or  deposits  with  the 
Bank  of  England,  say,  ;^100  million,  they  can  safely  maintain 
their  credits — ^that  is,  their  deposits,  which  result  chiefly  from 
loans,  at  from  £500  to  £1,000  million. 

How  the  Government  War  Loans  Were  Financed 

If  this  point  has  been  made  clear  we  are  now  in  a  position 
to  understand  how  banking  methods  were  applied  to  the  war 
financing. 


HOW   THE    BANKS    HELPED    FINANCE   THE   WAR  35 

In  the  case  of  the  large  loans,  it  was  customary  to  divide 
the  payments  into  several  instalments  spread  over  a  period 
of  weeks.  The  reason  for  this  arrangement  will  be  apparent 
when  the  process  of  settlement  is  considered. 

The  amount  which  the  banks  could  conveniently  handle 
in  one  payment  was  determined  by  their  reserve,  which 
consisted  chiefly  of  their  deposits  with  the  Bank  of  England. 

The  process  of  payment  was  likened  by  the  late  Chairman 
of  the  London  Joint  City  and  Midland  Bank,  Sir  Edward  H. 
Holden,  to  the  revolutions  of  a  wheel. 

"  The  banks  place  in  the  wheel  the  payments  they  make 
for  those  customers  who  have  subscribed  for  the  loans  ;  the 
wheel  carries  these  payments  to  the  credit  of  the  Government 
with  the  Bank  of  England,  and  the  subscribers  receive  their 
securities  ;  the  Government  then  places  in  the  wheel  cheques, 
in  payment  of  commodities  received  and  services  rendered, 
for  conveyance  to  their  creditors,  and  the  creditors  then  use 
the  wheel  to  carry  these  cheques  to  the  credit  of  their  accounts 
with  their  banks,  which  re-estabHshes  the  banks'  reserves 
and  prepares  them  for  another  instalment."  In  the  case 
of  Treasury  bills,  and  other  securities  sold  from  week  to 
week  in  relatively  small  amounts,  the  revolution  of  the  wheel 
was  rapid  enough  to  keep  pace  with  the  new  borrowing,  but  in 
the  case  of  the  large  loans  it  was  found  advisable  to  break  up 
the  payments  into  instalments,  so  that  each  instalment 
might  have  time  to  get  through  the  Bank  of  England,  through 
the  business  firms,  and  back  into  the  banks  before  another 
instalment  was  required. 

One  method  by  which  the  banks  developed  an  ability  to 
finance  the  stupendous  needs  of  the  Government  was  through 
a  utihzation  of  the  credit  facilities  of  the  Bank  of  England. 
To  increase  their  clients'  ability  and  their  own  ability  to 
invest  in  Government  issues  they  would  borrow  of  the  Bank 
of  England.  These  loans  would  increase  their  deposits  with 
the  Bank  of  England,  which  as  reserves  would  increase  their 
ability  to  grant  to  their  own  chents  loans  equivalent  to,  say, 
five  times  such  deposits. 


36  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

Ways  and  Means  Advances 

Another  and  most  important  way  in  which  the  banks  were 
used  to  finance  the  war  was  through  the  creation  of  direct 
credits  by  the  Bank  of  England  in  favour  of  the  Government. 
These  credits  are  known  as  "  Ways  and  Means  "  advances 
How  the  Government  benefited  by  these  advances  and  how 
they  operated  to  create  credits  with  other  banks  we  will  allow 
Lord  Cunhffe's  "  Committee  on  Currency  and  Foreign 
Exchanges  after  the  War  "   to  tell  us. 

In  their  final  report,  laid  before  Parhament  in  December, 
1919,  the  Committee  draw  attention  "  to  the  extensive  use 
made  during  the  war  of  the  system  of  Ways  and  Means  Ad- 
vances from  the  Bank  of  England  "  and  then  go  on  to  say  : 
"  The  powers  given  to  the  Government  by  Parhament  to 
borrow  from  the  Bank  of  England  in  the  form  of  an  overdraft 
on  the  credit  of  Ways  and  Means  were,  as  the  name  implies, 
intended  to  enable  the  Government  to  anticipate  receipts 
from  revenue  or  permanent  borrowings  for  a  brief  period  only. 
Indeed,  Parhament,  by  expressly  providing  that  all  such 
advances  should  be  repaid  in  the  quarter  following  that  in 
which  they  were  obtained,  showed  that  it  had  no  intention  of 
bestowing  upon  the  Government  the  power  of  securing  an 
overdraft  of  indefinite  duration  and  amount.  Under  the 
exigencies  of  war  finance  the  Government  found  it  necessary  to 
reborrow  in  each  quarter  on  the  credit  of  Ways  and  Means  the 
amount  needed  to  enable  them  to  comply  with  the  statutory 
requirement  that  the  previous  quarter's  Ways  and  Means 
Advances  should  be  repaid,  with  the  result  that  the  total 
outstanding  advances  remained  for  a  long  time  at  a  high 
figure.  We  are  glad  to  see  that  efforts  are  now  being  made  to 
reduce  this  overdraft  to  more  moderate  dimensions. 

"  We  therefore  hope,  now  that  the  conditions  are  less 
abnormal,  that  the  Government  will  confine  its  use  of  Ways 
and  Means  Advances  from  the  Bank  of  England  to  providing 
for  purely  temporary  necessities.  Such  advances  afford  a 
legitimate  method  of  tiding  over  a  few  weeks'  shortage,  but 


HOW   THE    BANKS    HELPED    FINANCE   THE    WAR  37 

are     entirely    unsuitable     for    borrowings    over    a    longer 
period," 

In  their  interim  report,  submitted  in  August,  1918,  the 
Committee  explain  how  these  advances  operated  to  swell 
bank  deposits  and  loans  :  "  This  process  has  had  results  of 
such  far-reaching  importance  that  it  may  be  useful  to  set  out 
in  detail  the  manner  in  which  it  operates.  Suppose,  for 
example,  that  in  a  given  week  the  Government  require 
;^10  milhon  over  and  above  the  receipts  from  taxation  and 
loans  from  the  pubHc.  They  apply  for  an  advance  from  the 
Bank  of  England,  which  by  a  book  entry  places  the  amount 
required  to  the  credit  of  Public  Deposits  in  the  same  way  as 
any  other  banker  credits  the  account  of  a  customer  when  he 
grants  him  temporary  accommodation.  The  amount  is  then 
paid  out  to  contractors  and  other  Government  creditors,  and 
passes,  when  the  cheques  are  cleared,  to  the  credit  of  their 
bankers  in  the  books  of  the  Bank  of  England — in  other  words, 
is  transferred  from  "  Pubhc  "  to  "  Other  "  deposits,  the 
effect  of  the  whole  transaction  thus  being  to  increase  by 
£10  million  the  purchasing  power  in  the  hands  of  the  public  in 
the  form  of  deposits  in  the  joint -stock  banks  and  the  bankers' 
cash  at  the  Bank  of  England  by  the  same  amount.  The 
bankers'  HabiUties  to  depositors  having  thus  increased  by 
;^10  million  and  their  cash  reserves  by  an  equal  amount,  their 
proportion  of  cash  to  habilities  (which  was  normally  before  the 
war  something  under  20  per  cent.)  is  improved,  with  the  result 
that  they  are  in  a  position  to  make  advances  to  their  customers 
to  an  amount  equal  to  four  or  five  times  the  sum  added  to  their 
cash  reserves,  or,  in  the  absence  of  demand  for  such  accommo- 
dation, to  increase  their  investments  by  the  difference  between 
the  cash  received  and  the  proportion  they  require  to  hold 
against  the  increase  of  their  deposit  habilities.  Since  the 
outbreak  of  war  it  is  the  second  procedure  which  has  in  the 
main  been  followed,  the  surplus  cash  having  been  used  to 
subscribe  for  Treasury  Bills  and  other  Government  securities. 
The  money  so  subscribed  has  again  been  spent  by  the  Govern- 
ment and  returned  in  the  manner  above  described  to  the 


38  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

bankers'  cash  balances,  the  process  being  repeated  again  and 
again,  until  each  ;^10  million  originally  advanced  by  the 
Bank  of  England  has  created  new  deposits  representing  new 
purchasing  power  to  several  times  that  amount." 

How  this  process  actually  worked  out  is  described  in  the 
next  chapter. 


CHAPTER  VI 

THE  WAR  CREDIT   STRUCTURE 

(1914-1920) 

The  Credit  Structure  tables  to  which  the  attention  of  the 
reader  is  now  called  are  based  upon  the  pubhshed  returns 
of  the  Government  and  of  the  banks  made  nearest  to  the  end 
of  the  calendar  years  1913  to  1919  inclusive.  The  purpose 
is  to  compare  the  total  liabilities  of  the  nation  on  account 
of  the  debt  with  the  assets  of  the  banks  and  to  compare  the 
currency  and  the  bank  deposits  with  the  gold  coin  and  bullion 
impounded  in  the  coffers  of  the  joint -stock  banks  and  of  the 
Bank  of  England.  The  statistical  data  used  are  taken  from 
the  weekly  reports  of  the  Bank  of  England,  from  the  Cunhffe 
Committee's  reports,  from  a  paper  on  the  Statistical  Aspects 
of  Inflation,  by  Professor  J.  Shield  Nicholson,  read  before 
the  Royal  Statistical  Society  in  June,  1917,  from  the  Banker's 
Magazine  (London),  and  from  the  columns  of  The  Economist 
and  of  The  Statist. 

The   National   Debt  and  Bank  Assets 

Table  I  compares  the  year  to  year  changes  in  the  national 
debt  with  the  corresponding  changes  in  bank  assets.  It  is 
somewhat  of  a  surprise  that  the  Bank  of  England's  holdings 
of  Government  securities  do  not  more  fully  reflect  the  changes 
in  the  Ways  and  Means  advances.  However,  taking  the 
entire  debt  fluctuations  into  consideration  it  is  apparent  that 
the  assets  of  the  banks  have  fluctuated  with  the  changes  in  the 
debt,  and  that  bank  assets  have  grown  as  the  national  debt 
has  grown.  It  is  not  possible  to  make  close  comparisons 
because  call  loans  are  reported  together  with  cash  in  hand  and 
at  the  Bank  of  England.  It  is  probable  that  some  of  the 
banks  treat  Treasury  bills  as  equivalent  to  cash,  while  others 
treat  them  as  investments  or  as  discounted  paper.  It  is 
interesting  to  note  that  most  of  the  debt  of  the  Government 

39 


THE   WAR   CREDIT   STRUCTURE  41 

must  be  held  outside  of  the  banks  as  the  entire  increase  in 
the  assets  of  the  banks,  outside  of  plant,  from  the  close  of 
1913  to  the  close  of  1919  amounting  to  around  £1,200  million, 
was  only  about  one -sixth  the  increase  of  the  debt.  If  then 
we  make  the  unlikely  assumption  that  the  entire  increase  in 
the  assets  of  the  banks  is  represented  by  holdings  of  National 
debt  or  loans  thereon  it  is  evident  that  over  £6,000  million 
of  debt  has  found  permanent  lodgment  with  private  and 
corporate  investors  other  than  the  banks,  and  that  they  are 
not  borrowing  against  such  holdings. ^  The  probabihty  is 
that  a  much  larger  amount  is  so  held,  as  the  increased  assets 
of  the  banks  must  represent,  in  addition  to  Government 
obligations,  large  increased  holdings  of  business  paper. 

Note  and  Deposit  Currency  v.  the  Gold  Reserves 

Tables  II  and  III  permit  of  a  year  to  year  study  of  the 
growth  of  the  note  and  deposit  habilities  of  the  banks,  which 
may  be  said  to  represent  the  credit  facilities  of  the  nation, 
and  a  comparison  of  this  credit  structure  with  the  specie 
reserves.     (See  pages  42  and  44.) 

The  interesting  conclusion  at  which  we  arrive  is  that  in 
the  case  of  the  Treasury  Notes,  Bank  of  England  Notes  in 
circulation  and  bank  deposits,  the  percentage  of  reserve  in 
each  instance  has  fallen.  This  is  especially  noticeable  in 
connection  with  deposits  where  the  estimated  effective  gold 
reserve  held  against  all  deposits  on  31st  December,  1919,  was 
only  2-3  per  cent.  While  the  entire  credit  structure  increased 
from  £1,227  million  in  December,  1913,  to  £3,002  million  in 
December,  1919,  an  increase  of  144-7  per  cent.,  the  specie 
reserves  held  increased  only  from  £85  milhon  to  £160  milHon, 
a  decrease  from  6-9  per  cent,  of  the  HabiUties  to  5-3  per  cent. 

It  is  evident  that  in  the  diminishing  gold  reserve  and  the 

increasing  liabilities  we  have  a  serious  situation. 

^  This  is  particularly  true  in  view  of  the  fact  that,  included  in  this 
;^6,000  million  of  debt,  would,  of  course,  be  the  indebtedness  to  the 
Government  of  the  United  States  and  to  other  foreign  governments, 
as  well  as  that  to  the  British  Government  itself,  under  guise  of  the 
Currency  Note  Redemption  Account,  the  Savings  Banks  Account  and 
other  public  funds  which  hold  Government  securities. 


«■ 

(S 

0 

aor»  —  !■* 

•«' 

t~ 

•*CD 

00 

—  —  t^-  3)    Op  |m  e^ 

r^M   t^ 

r. 

.2 

vpSi 

0    1 

r^  cs  CO   to 

0 

I      1 

10  1 

CO  in 

o> 

—  en  01  c^    r-    —  — 

10-  :^ 

■* 

•8 

5S5 

0    1 

0  r^  <o   -* 

<c 

1      1 

CO  1 

00  o> 

I^ 

CO  0  M  —    c^  1  CO  CO 

CD  CO  ^ 

■* 

c 

T 

-c^c^,— 

(N 

M 

^" 

" 

|-|„- 

C^  — 

" 

a 

1 

1 

eo 

"O 

S2 

0  — 

«*©«  lin  Ice 

COO>^   i-N  00 

»lfll-* 

tOift^CD 

0  '-"l-C^ 

0-9 

-n 

1     .f 

rCco 

CD  — eflcn" 

« 

—"  S'  cd" 

00  05  1  X 

,*:;  cfrs 

—   05" 

co'oT 

!@ 

CO 

IDNM 

<j> 

R 

1/5 

S- 

->    M 

gcoo>co 

5?   5° 

CO  •* 

j:,05 

•9     1 

.-T 

^     ^ 

^ 

•Hll 

8     8 

a  > 

1 

'00 

«o 

1 

1 

t>. 

\      « 

CO 

•^  st 

■^  0  — 

^ 

r»t*u3 

a>_'o 

-    05 

t%rt 

C4CD 

00 

r^  CO  .^  r^ 

„ 

05 -l" 

I^O>  '« 

U3 

a 

co" 

00000 

rC  ^ 

''-ffi 

00 

o>"o 

o>" 

o'cOlNt-" 

^ 

co" 

co"co*  g 

5» 

1  « 

1" 

ONco  cc  N 

—                —    U5 

—  1/5 

5  ■" 

•^00 

05 

r;CD5C  10 
00.1N-  X 

■0 

CO 
IN 

^-2 

•»■  in   0 
c<i"  cs 

in 

V 

U5 

m 

>,     0 

0> 

in 

1 

CO 

c**  ^ 

1 

1 

1 

PI 

CO 

CO 

flo_«(n  !oo.!o_ 

CD-* 

om 
c» 

CO  00 

cd"-*" 

-. 

■*— _CO,CO_ 

Se-1  Sin 

■*  |u5-0< 

—   ^^" 

00  U5 

«. 

in 

1  oi 

ONeo  lo   t~. 

IN  in 

"2 

M  — 

■>r 

2£J 

H  eo  u 

d 

1  '^ 

'^ 

N 

N 

|«_M  — 

CON 

e« 

t;«- 

00 

00 
1      "* 

K 

.s'Sfl 
<«  1--- 

"^* 

t^ 

■*«,00 

0 

r^ 

05_->_  r^  00 

o_-*    ■* 

eo>«co_r» 

00  iN>n 

i^<s  lo»  1— 

-^1 

2 

i>r 

co'cTco 

0" 

r^ 

05"  r^ 

0 

pfoo  0 

i«co"orV 

!£  £ 

S5S  S 

■«■ 

\^ 

t^-«M 

e^ 

g 

MCO 

?;j: 

eo>o    O) 

CD  05  05  -^ 

CO  — 

r>^i  00 

—   OJ   1 

1i 

U5 

1     ^ 

1       I'' 

So  fc 

2o  «>.- 

„ 

ooieo 

^ 

oi_ 

0_CD_ 

COU5 

—  Tf     U5 

0)C0_r-»_^iM_:'* 

05  00 

C0  05_ 

la 

IN 

0 

— "lOO    00 

00 

eaoJ' 

cc" 

coco"  oT 

-fcD'co-Qs"  ■* 

co" 

coco" 

0 

•|°-i£o 

1:2 

t^--<s 

0 

IN 

COM 

2i« 

U5  ^ 

<c 

mcD  wco   t 

5-" 

05  — 
—  CD. 

t^ 

hi 

■>1" 

'"in 
eo 

2 

CO 

o    . 

*-3       .a 

ui 

co" 

t^  c»  — _'r>^ 

a>'M''cc|od 

Q0_ 

inco_ 

r-,o 

r»  05 

05"--* 

^. 

CD  t0.t>._05_ 

M'o'rCc-r 

00 

co" 

■*o 
10 

iH 

- 

H  « 

t  0 

cc  r-.  --  lo> 

0 

CO  C4 

•* 

■•J-  — 

^ 

05  -» c^co 

■*  10  _ 

■*o 

CC 

O) 

1  - 

!N 

"M 

»-' 

»"" 

05  — 

IN     •*  n 

—  ■* 

>o 

•^  "  0 

c/)  .^ 

rH 

♦* 

nt 

CO 

0 

CO 

s§ 

' 



I                          '        1 

s^ 

0-* 
in  00 

0   1- 

CO-* 

-co" 

r-^co 

o>_o, 
to-x" 

05_ 

cDinino>_  lol-'ro 
i/TlN -TM-  iolo" 

•wo 

2l^ 

loeo 

00     — 

2S 

>r>  — 

CO   QQ 

c^c^ 

1/5 

05  CO  r*.  CO   CO  05  _^ 

COCK 
—  CM_ 

p  .en 

i^  _ 

0)   V 

o  2 

M 

T  s 

0 

iCO 

S^ 

b: 

1 

t 

S-° 

Qi-M 

o_ 

eo_r»'t  !•*_'•* 

r» 

t>.IN 

CO—    I- 

■>j'05_rN— _  —  i« 

r-^in 

Oil 

CD 

1^ 

<  i 

^  i 

CO 

rC 

N  C^OO    00    lO 

c^ 

c4 

o".-"  — * 

oT "nor-."  co"  •«  ,-. 
0  c-i  t^  C4  m  0  ° 

eJ-*" 

r^   1 

m           <D  •* 

^   1 

e^« 

—  CO  t^ 

CNO 

CO 

S 

'^ 

1 

•^  r-t 

00  —           ^'"^ 

^  '^ 

®1 

•-t    fH 

w  1 

c* 

1     ^ 

CD 

^2 

S! 

H     . 

►>. 

1 

_ 

....  1 
0 

Z 

§■(5 

S'C     •    • 
2'-' 

.    .     . 

•SB 
g.|    2 

l-l  1 

1 

...       .^ 
3   .   .     .  -g 

«g       •     • 

•2-g 
So     •   • 

.^  u 

•< 
H 

■■a  ■ 

1       1 

0  rt  - 

M 

.2               g 

•1-=  "2 

"« 

^ 

3  0  1  c  c  a  ^  (-1 

^.2 

C  m 
a  0  ^ 

■5,0    ^ 

w^    1.3 
^  >.  c  S 

(£0  J 

•5,   0 

w     1 
0     a 
M     -5 

C 

1    .   .   .   .t 

%    ■ 

a 

a 

m 

=3  2 

Til 

C  K 

21=55   ^ 
3S5    fe 

s 

it 

2  « 

c3      "0 

0                    Q     S 

0  a.w    Q, 

t/l     CO**-!     Vj 

0 

Q 

1/5 

1 

S.S 

THE   WAR   CREDIT  STRUCTURE  43 

High  Prices  and  Bank  Credits 

Present  high  prices  are  easily  explainable  when  it  is 
considered  that  the  actual  volume  of  commodities  re- 
quired to  support  the  people  of  Great  Britain  is  probably 
no  more  to-day,  and  possibly  is  less,  than  it  was  before 
the  war. 

It  is  doubtful,  too,  whether  the  physical  volume  of  trade 
has  increased  during  the  war  period.  Estimates  made  for 
the  United  States  by  Professor  E.  W.  Kemmerer  of  Princeton 
University  show  that  the  physical  volume  of  trade  for  our 
country  increased  from  1913  to  1919  only  9-6  per  cent.  There 
is  no  similar  computation  available  for  England,  but  Professor 
Kemmerer  beUeves  it  to  be  unlikely  that  the  actual  increase 
there  in  the  physical  volume  of  trade  during  the  same  years 
has  been  as  great  as  in  the  United  States,  He  thinks  that 
it  has  been  less.  If  this  is  true,  then  it  is  easy  to  under- 
stand why  prices  have  advanced  in  the  marked  manner 
shown  by  The  Economist  Index  Number  of  commodity  prices 
printed  below.  If  the  adjustment  between  the  currency  and 
the  credit  structure  and  the  physical  volume  of  trade  is 
properly  made  the  normal  variation  in  the  rise  and  fall  of 
general  prices  will  not  be  great.  There  will  be  seasonal 
declines  when  new  crops  come  in  and  advances  as  the  bins 
become  empty,  but,  as  a  rule,  there  will  be  no  marked  deviation 
from  a  general  average. 

But  if  the  credit  structure  is  dislocated,  or  if  there  is  an 
unusual  harvest  or  an  unusual  demand  such  as  is  caused  by 
war,  then  the  price  level  will  reflect  these  conditions.  Let 
us  see  what  happened  between  1913  and  1920.  Taking  the 
price  index  of  31st  December,  1913,  as  100  we  find  that  in 
1915  prices  rose  38  per  cent,  above  the  base.  During  the 
height  of  the  war,  in  1916,  1917  and  1918,  they  averaged  over 
twice  the  base  price,  but  with  the  war  over  they  kept  soaring 
and  by  the  close  of  1919  they  were  nearly  three  times  the 
pre-war  prices. 


THE   WAR   CREDIT    STRUCTURE 


45 


Here  are  the  figures- 


ECONOMIST  "   PRICE   INDEX. 


Increase 

Increase 

per  cent. 

)ec.  31. 

Index  No. 

over  1913. 

over  1913 

1913   . 

2623 

Base 

100-0 

1914   . 

2800 

177 

106-7 

1915   . 

3634 

1011 

138-5 

1916   . 

4908 

2285 

187-1 

1917  . 

5845 

3222 

222-8 

1918  . 

6094 

3471 

232-3 

1919  . 

7364 

4741 

280-7 

As  one  measure  of  inflation  we  may  profitably  study  the 
comparative  volumes  of  imported  goods  and  their  values  at 
the  custom  house.  There  is  no  common  denominator  of 
quantities.  Some  things  are  measured  by  tons,  others  by 
pounds,  and  others  still  by  numbers.  Although  we  cannot 
add  together  all  of  the  commodities  imported  and  largely 
consumed  at  home,  we  can  select  certain  of  the  more  important 
commodities  and  take  their  testimony.  This  we  have  done 
in  the  following  table — 


ONE   EVIDENCE   OF   INFLATION. 

Quantities  and  Values  of  Imports  Compared. 

( In  Millions.) 


1913. 

191 

8. 

1919. 

Calendar  Year. 

Quanti- 
ties. 

Value. 

Quanti- 
ties. 

Value. 

Quanti- 
ties. 

Value. 

Wheat,  cwt. 

105 

;^44 

58 

£53 

71 

;^68 

Beef,  cwt. 

9 

16 

7 

36 

6 

30 

Sugar,  lb. 

o9 

23 

26 

34 

32 

54 

Tea,  lb. 

365 

14 

463 

29 

510 

34 

Cotton,  cwt. 

22 

70 

15 

150 

19 

190 

V^ool,  lb. 

800 

34 

413 

36 

1,042 

97 

Thus  we  see  that  the  quantities  of  wheat,  beef,  sugar, 
cotton  and  wool  imported  in  1918  were  materially  less  than 
the  quantities  imported  in  1913  and  yet  the  money  values 
were  greatly  higher.  While  in  1918  and  1919  the  imports 
of  tea,  and  in  1919  the  imports  of  both  tea  and  wool,  exceeded 


46  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

in  quantity  the  imports  of  1913,  yet  in  every  case  the  relative 
money  values  of  the  imports  is  materially  greater  than  the 
values  of  1913.  Could  there  be  a  better  illustration  of  the 
manner  in  which  a  disproportionate  increase  in  the  credit 
structure  leads  to  increases  in  prices  ? 

The  imperative  need  for  a  firm  handling  of  the  credit 
situation  is  apparent.  Not  only  in  England,  but  in  all  other 
countries,  the  world  over,  must  there  be  practised  drastic 
economies  in  government  expenditures  and  every  effort  put 
forth  to  meet  expenses  from  taxation.  Government  borrow- 
ing, except  for  refunding  purposes,  should  cease.  At  the 
same  time  the  people  must  settle  down  to  productive  work. 
Meanwhile  it  is  the  obvious  duty  of  the  banks  to  hold  specula- 
tion in  check  and  gently  but  firnily  to  reverse  the  process 
of  inflation  which  the  war  made  necessary. 

The  tables  bring  out  in  bold  relief  the  manner  in  which 
bank  credits  were  used  to  win  the  war.  They  also  show  the 
dizzy  heights  from  which  the  business  of  the  world  must 
cautiously  descend  before  normal  conditions,  nationally  or 
internationally,  can  be  resumed. 

We  may  now  profitably  retrace  our  steps  and  consider  the 
history  of  English  public  finance  from  its  genesis  in  Norman 
days. 


CHAPTER  VII 

CROWN   FINANCE 

(1066-1688) 
The  foundations  of  England's  present-day  financial  structure 
were  laid  broad  and  deep  centuries  ago.  The  Exchequer 
and  the  Treasury  can  trace  their  lineage  directly  to  Norman 
times,  possibly  even  to  the  times  of  the  great  Alfred  himself. 
There  have  been  a  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  and  a  Treasurer 
since  the  days  of  Henry  II — that  is,  since  the  middle  of  the 
twelfth    century. 

Books  of  account,  or  rather  Rolls  of  account  (for  the 
accounts  were  written  on  parchment  which  was  made  up  in 
long  strips  which  were  rolled  up  when  not  in  use)  are  extant 
from  the  reign  of  this  king. 

The  early  kings  had  extensive  demesnes  from  which  they 
derived  a  large  part  of  their  revenue.  Aside  from  this  source 
of  income,  the  receipts  of  the  Exchequer  during  all  of  these 
ages  have  come  from  three  principal  sources — from  internal 
taxation,  from  customs  and  from  borrowing. 

The  history  of  the  revenues  of  England's  kings  is  inseparably 
bound  up  with  the  history  of  the  development  of  her  civil 
rights.  The  fight  for  the  control  of  the  purse,  first  formulated 
in  the  terms  of  Magna  Charta,  wrung  by  the  barons  from 
the  tyrant  John  in  1215,  was  only  won  after  four  and  a 
half  centmies  of  conflict  between  sovereign  and  people. 
The  word  "  people  "  is  used  here  and  elsewhere  in  these 
chapters  as  a  generic  term  referring  to  those  members  of 
the  body  politic  who  from  time  to  time  were  capable  of  taking 
part  in  public  affairs.  In  the  time  of  the  Norman  Kings 
probably  not  over  a  fifth  of  the  inhabitants  could  be  so 
classified.  The  growth  of  general  intelligence  which  has  at 
last,  in  a  sense,  fitted  the  greater  part  of  the  people  to  exercise 
the  rights  and  duties  of  citizenship  only  came  into  full  flower 
within  the  past  century. 

47 


48  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

The  effort  on  the  part  of  the  sovereign  was  to  secure  an 
income  from  other  sources  than  from  taxation.  The  people, 
on  the  other  hand,  found  that  the  only  way  to  insure  just 
treatment  by  the  sovereign  was  to  keep  him  poor,  so  that  he 
needs  must  come  to  them  for  an  "  aid  "  or  a  "  grant."  On 
such  occasions  they  could  insist  on  a  redress  of  grievances  or 
on  a  surrender  of  some  part  of  the  royal  prerogative  before  the 
grant  was  voted.  Thus,  little  by  little,  one  by  one,  were 
secured  the  liberties  which  old  England  and  oiuselves  now 
enjoy.  "  No  taxation  without  representation  "  was  not  a 
new  formula  in  1776.  The  principle  had  its  beginnings 
centuries  before. 

We  are  to  study  English  public  finance  since  the  Revolution 
of  1688,  but  in  order  that  we  may  do  so  intelligently,  we 
must  first  consider  the  developments  of  the  six  centuries 
which  elapsed  between  the  advent  of  William  the  Conqueror 
in  1066  and  of  that  other  William  who  came  over  from 
Holland  in  1688,  at  the  request  of  a  little  band  of  patriots, 
to  help  them  rear  a  constitutional  government  on  the  founda- 
tion which  had  been  laid  by  their  forefathers  and  upon  which 
the  Stuart  Kings  had  tried  in  vain  to  build  for  autocracy. 

This  later  William  had  expected  to  receive  the  usual  life 
grant  from  the  customs  which  the  kings  and  queens  from 
time  inunemorial  had  enjoyed.  The  Commons  declined  to 
make  this  grant  for  a  longer  period  than  four  years.  Thence- 
forward the  power  of  the  King  steadily  declined  and  the 
rights  of  the  people  steadily  increased  until  we  have  in  the 
England  of  to-day  one  of  the  greatest  democracies  of  the 
world  and  of  any  time  ;  a  democracy  the  government  of  which 
is  more  sensitive,  perhaps,  to  the  will  of  the  people  than  is  the 
case  even  in  our  own  United  States. 

Let  us  now  turn  oui  attention  to  the  eleventh  century  and 
trace  the  coiuse  of  public  finance  to  our  own  day. 

We  will  be  able  to  deal  only  with  the  facts  of  greatest 
importance. 


CHAPTER  VIII 

REVENUES  OF  THE  ANGLO-SAXON    KINGS 

When  William  the  Conqueror  arrived  from  Normandy,  what 
revenue  system  did  he  find  and  what  new  ideas  did  he  bring 
with  him  from  his  Norman  home  ? 

The  King's  Demesne 

First  of  all  he  found  that  Alfred  and  his  successors  down 
to  the  time  of  Edward  (called  "the  Confessor  ")  had  enjoyed 
great  landed  possessions,  and  flocks  and  herds.  They  had 
possessed  rude  castles,  jewels  and  richly  embroidered  robes  of 
state.  They  had  had  a  royal  hoard  kept  in  the  King's  castle 
where  there  were  leather  bags  filled  with  the  roughly  minted 
silver  coins  of  the  time. 

The  germ  of  the  feudal  system  was  there  also. 

Trinoda  Necessitas 

The  revenues  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  kings  were  derived  from 
their  estates,  from  fines  imposed  as  penalties  for  the  infraction 
of  the  rude  laws  of  the  times,  and  from  certain  taxes  to  which 
every  landowner  was  subject.  These  taxes,  known  as  the 
trinoda  necessitas,  were  at  first  exacted  in  kind  ;  every  free- 
man when  legally  called  upon  was  obliged  to  appear  in  person 
for  the  purpose  of  repelling  the  enemy,  here-geld  ;  or  when  a 
city,  town  or  castle  or  a  fortress  for  the  public  defence  was  to 
be  built  or  repaired,  burg-bote  ;  or  when  bridges  necessary  for 
the  internal  commerce  of  the  country  were  to  be  built  or 
repaired,  brig-bote.  In  time  it  came  about  as  a  matter  of 
convenience  that  for  payments  in  personal  services  or 
materials  a  money  equivalent  was  given. 

Dane-geld 

These  taxes,  intended  to  meet  the  ordinary  contingencies 
of  day-to-day  life,  did  not  sufiice  to  repel  the  attacks  of  the 

49 

4— (1823) 


50  ENGLISH  PUBLIC   FINANCE 

Danes.  These  were  not  infrequent,  and  were  marked  with 
every  species  of  devastation  and  horror.  Therefore,  in  the 
latter  part  of  the  tenth  century  it  became  the  custom  to  bribe 
the  Danes  to  stay  in  their  own  country.  As  usually  happens 
in  cases  of  bribery  and  blackmail,  the  Danes  continually 
demanded  renewed  and  larger  payments.  The  tax  which  was 
laid  to  obtain  this  money  was  known  as  Dane-geld,  or  Dane- 
money,  and  was  raised  by  a  levy  upon  lands.  Ultimately 
this  tax  became  a  regular  source  of  income  to  the  Crown. 
Laid  ostensibly  for  the  defence  of  the  country  against  the 
Danes,  actually  it  was  used  for  any  purpose  to  which  it  might 
be  applied  by  the  King.  This  tax  was  very  odious  to  the 
people,  but  persisted,  except  during  the  reign  of  Edward  and 
Harold,  until  long  after  the  Norman  Conquest.  It  is  the 
first  instance  in  British  history  of  a  tax  laid  upon  lands.  It 
was  imposed  at  so  much  a  hide,  a  measure  which  may  be 
roughly  taken  to  have  been  about  one  hundred  acres. 

Other  Anglo-Saxon  taxes  which  endiired  to  later  times 
were  the  hearth  tax,  a  payment  to  the  King  for  every  hearth 
in  all  homes,  except  those  of  the  very  poor,  and  ship-geld, 
money  raised  to  build  and  equip  a  ship  or  ships  for  use  in 
repelling  invasion.  This  latter  tax  was  levied,  as  a  rule,  only 
on  the  coast  towns. 

Purveyance 

Under  a  system  known  as  purveyance,  it  was  customary 
for  the  reeves,  or  sheriffs,  to  make  a  levy  of  goods  to  be  used 
for  the  maintenance  of  the  royal  household.  The  King  was 
entitled  also  to  a  share  of  the  produce  of  the  folk  land — ^that 
is,  land  held  in  common  by  the  residents  of  different  neigh- 
bourhoods. 

Customs 

Probably  the  Anglo-Saxon  kings  had  some  revenue  from 
home  and  foreign  trade.  We  find  smiths  and  carpenters, 
fishermen  and  millers,  weavers  and  architects  mentioned  in 
old  chronicles  as  belonging  to  various  convents.     We  also 


REVENUES   OF  THE  ANGLO-SAXON    KINGS  51 

find  the  merchant  asserting  the  dignity  of  his  calling.  "  I  am 
useful,"  he  says,  "  to  the  King  and  his  nobles,  to  rich  men  and 
to  common  folk.  I  enter  my  ship  with  my  merchandise, 
and  sail  across  the  seas  and  sell  my  wares,  and  buy  dear 
things  which  are  not  produced  in  this  land,  and  bring  them 
with  great  danger  for  your  good."  And  then  he  tells  what 
he  brings — "  skin,  wine,  oil,  costly  gems  and  gold,  various 
garments,  pigments,  brass,  copper,  tin,  glass,"  and  so  on. 
This  whole  question  of  foreign  commerce  from  these  early 
days  until  now  is  of  intense  interest,  and  is  as  much  bound  up 
in  the  story  of  England's  business  life  as  the  question  of 
public  finance  is  inseparable  from  a  study  of  the  development 
of  England's  liberties. 

Licences 

In  Anglo-Saxon  and  Anglo-Norman  times,  fairs  took  the 
place  of  shops.  In  the  beginning  they  had  a  distinctively 
religious  character  which  they  gradually  lost.  The  people 
were  in  the  habit  of  coming  together  to  perform  their  devotions 
in  the  churches  at  night-time  with  candles  burning.  They 
would  gather  in  the  church  porches  and  yards  for  social 
intercourse,  and  finally  "  fell  to  lechery  and  songs,  dancing, 
harping,  piping  and  also  to  gluttony  and  sin."  Thus  was  laid 
the  foundation  for  those  periodical  fairs  which  are  held  even 
to  the  present  day.  It  was  natural  that  where  the  people 
were  gathered  together  the  merchants  should  bring  their 
wares  for  sale.  This  was  also  a  great  convenience  to  the 
people  when  the  means  of  travelling  were  bad,  and  oppor- 
tunities to  supply  their  needs  were  scant.  At  these  fairs  they 
could  barter  their  sheepskins  and  agricultiual  produce,  or  any 
of  their  rough  local  manufactures,  for  the  wares  of  the  mer- 
chants. In  time  these  fairs  became  markets  which  were  held 
at  regular  places  at  regular  intervals,  probably  very  much  as 
is  still  the  custom  in  Russia  where  the  annual  fairs  play  such 
an  important  part  in  the  commercial  life  of  the  people.  It 
need  scarcely  be  pointed  out  that  the  thrifty  Anglo-Saxon 
and  Anglo-Norman  kings  turned  this  custom  to  good  account 


52  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

as  a  means  of  revenue,  charging  fines,  or,  as  we  would  say, 
licence  fees,  for  the  right  to  hold  the  fairs. 

The  Exchequer 

There  was  in  use,  too,  in  all  probability,  a  system  for 
collecting  and  caring  for  the  King's  revenues  very  similar  to 
the  system  which  William  had  in  use  in  Normandy — a  system 
which  persisted  in  part  at  least  until  the  times  of  Queen 
Victoria,  and  in  the  names  of  certain  officials  has  lasted  even  to 
this  year  of  grace  1920.  This  system  and  the  modern  treasury 
department  are  described  in  a  subsequent  chapter  on  the 
Exchequer. 


CHAPTER   IX 

THE    king's    prerogative 

William  took  possession  of  all  the  royal  properties  and 
sources  of  revenue  and  grafted  on  to  these  the  Norman  feudal 
system  of  land  tenure. 

As  King,  William  claimed  the  royal  demesne,  the  royal 

forests  and  the  perquisites  of  royalty,  previously  described, 
enjoyed  by  his  Anglo-Saxon  predecessors. 

The  Royal  Demesne 

This  was  of  vast  extent.  There  were  three  divisions  : — 
the  forests  which  formed  the  King's  hunting  grounds  and 
were  secured  against  intruders  by  a  savage  code  of  special 
regulations  known  as  the  forest  laws,  the  land  held  by  the 
King's  rural  tenants,  and  thirdly  the  holdings  of  urban  tenants. 
This  last-named  division  included  most  of  the  cities,  boroughs 
and  towns  of  the  Kingdom  which  originally  had  been  founded 
on  the  folklands.  The  rents  of  these  towns  were  collected 
by  the  sheriffs. 

All  of  the  tenants  of  the  royal  demesne  were  liable  to 
assist  the  King  on  any  occasion  of  special  expense — even  to 
the  tenth  part  of  their  goods. 

Feudal  Aids 

As  feudal  lord  he  claimed  the  so-called  feudal  aids,  namely, 
the  right  to  levy  a  tax  for  his  ransom  should  he  be  taken 
prisoner  by  an  enemy  ;  the  right  to  receive  a  generous 
contribution  from  his  people  when  his  son  was  invested 
with  the  privileges  of  knighthood  ;  and  of  a  corresponding 
contribution  upon  the  marriage  of  his  eldest  daughter,  to 
provide  her  with  a  dowry.  Under  the  feudal  system  the 
King,  in  addition  to  these  special  aids,  which  were  never 
surrendered  until  six  centuries  later,  was  entitled  in  time  of 
war  to  the  personal  services  of  his  knights,  who  must  attend 
him  with  a  complement  of  men,  equipped  for  service. 

53 


54  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

Purveyance 

Under  the  name  of  purveyance,  the  King  was  entitled  to 
impress  horses  and  vehicles  to  transport  him  and  his  entourage 
from  one  part  of  the  country  to  another.  He  was  entitled 
to  appropriate  any  food  or  other  articles  which  he  required, 
paying  for  them  such  prices  as  he  saw  fit  ;  this  was  called 
"  preemption,"  but  in  process  of  time  was  merged  with 
the  Anglo-Saxon  idea  of  purveyance  already  noticed  ;  the 
two  rights  going  under  the  name  of  purveyance.  This  con- 
stituted a  most  obnoxious  form  of  imposition  which  persisted 
for  several  centuries. 

Fines — Bona  Vacantia 

Another  source  of  income  was  from  fines  for  trespassing 
upon  the  King's  domains,  especially  for  taking  wild  animals 
or  even  wood  from  his  forests  or  fish  from  the  streams  therein. 
As  the  fountain  head  of  justice,  the  King  was  entitled  to  a 
share  of  the  fines  levied  upon  criminals  of  high  or  low  degree. 
All  treasure  trove,  i.e.  money,  plate,  or  bullion  found  hidden 
in  the  earth  ;  waifs,  or  goods  stolen  and  waived  ;  stray 
cattle,  wrecks,  or  large  fish  belonged  to  the  King.  These 
were  known  as  bona  vacantia.  The  custody  of  the  property 
of  idiots  and  any  profit  accruing  after  providing  for  their 
support  ;  also  estates  to  which  no  claim  could  be  made  by 
rightful  heirs  fell  under  this  head. 

If  all  of  these  sources  of  income  were  not  sufficient,  the 
King  might  debase  the  coinage  ;  he  might  ask  his  people  for 
presents — sometimes  called  contributions,  and  subsequently, 
by  the  Tudors,  benevolences  ;  or  he  might  simply  extort  or 
exact  gifts  or  call  for  loans  which  he  might  or  might  not  pay 
as  the  spirit  moved  him.  It  may  be  noted  here  that  based  on 
the  so-called  voluntaiy  offerings  to  the  King  an  additional 
10  per  cent,  was  levied  for  the  personal  use  of  his  Queen — ■ 
this  contribution  was  known  as  Queen's  gold. 

Having  seen  what  were  the  sources  of  the  King's  income  at 
the  time  of  the  Conquest  and  during  the  reign  of  the  Norman 
Kings,  we  may  now  consider  the  subsequent  developments. 


CHAPTER  X 

CROWN    REVENUES    SUBSEQUENT   TO   THE    NORMAN 
PERIOD 

(1154-1688) 

The  constant  effort  of  the  people  from  very  early  times, 
perhaps  not  at  first  a  very  definite  intention,  was  to  keep 
the  King  poor,  so  that  he  would  need  to  come  to  them  for 
suppHes.  Then,  by  withholding  money  grants  until  their 
grievances  were  remedied,  little  by  little  they  developed  the 
constitutional  rights  now  enjoyed. 

The  principal  sources  of  revenue  of  the  early  EngUsh  kings 
and  queens,  other  than  the  revenues  derived  from  their 
demesnes  and  prerogative  as  already  described,  were  the 
customs  duties,  internal  taxation,  borrowing  and  extortion 
in  various  forms. 

The  first  two  may  be  described  as  legitimate,  or  constitu- 
tional, sources  ;  the  last  as  a  method  of  evading  constitutional 
processes.  Borrowing  was  strictly  the  personal  act  and 
privilege  of  the  sovereign.  It  was  used  as  a  legitimate  means 
of  bridging  over  gaps  in  the  receipt  of  revenue.  Frequently, 
also,  it  was  used  as  a  means  of  avoiding  the  necessity  of  asking 
Parhament  for  a  grant.  It  was  often  only  a  disguised  form 
of  extortion. 

It  may  be  of  interest  briefly  to  consider  each  of  the  sources 
of  income. 

The  Customs 

The  King's  right  to  exact  tolls  on  goods  going  out  of  or 
entering  the  kingdom  is  supposed  to  have  grown  out  of  the 
idea  of  purveyance.  Certain  it  is  that  the  right  to  prisage — 
that  is,  to  take  goods  or  chattels  in  kind — and  to  the  collection 
of  tolls  or  duties  on  wool  and  other  exported  goods  was 
exercised  from  an  early  date  and  was  prized  by  all  the  kings 

55 


56  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

reigning  down  to  the  Revolution  as  one  of  the  choicest  of 
their  hereditary  privileges.  It  came  to  be  understood  that 
without  parliamentary  grant  the  King  could  collect  what 
are  called  in  Magna  Charta  "  the  ancient  and  equitable 
duties."  These  consisted  of  an  export  duty  which  was 
collected  on  wool,  wool-fells  (that  is,  skins  with  the  wool 
attached)  and  upon  leather.  The  King,  as  one  of  his  preroga- 
tives, was  entitled  to  two  casks  of  wine  out  of  every  cargo. 
This  right  was  afterwards  reduced  to  a  definite  tariff  on  wine 
and  was  known  as  the  "  New  Customs."  In  the  time  of 
Edward  I,  toward  the  end  of  the  thirteenth  century,  the 
custom  arose  of  granting  the  King,  for  life,  duties  known  as 
"  tunnage "  and  "  poundage."  These  duties  were  levied 
upon  every  tun  of  wine  and  upon  every  pound  of  merchandise 
imported  ;  also  at  times  upon  exports.  They  were  levied  in 
addition  to  the  old  and  new  customs  duties. 

In  addition  to  the  hereditary  duties  and  the  life  grant  of 
tunnage  and  poundage  the  King  received  customs  subsidies, 
as  they  were  called.  The  subsidy  was  a  parliamentary  grant 
in  excess  of  those  already  described.  These  grants  were 
made  from  time  to  time  as  called  for  by  the  exigencies  of  the 
King's  affairs.  In  times  of  war  they  were  greater  than  in 
times  of  peace.     They  were  always  granted  for  short  periods. 

The  customs  revenues  were  especially  prized  by  the  earlier 
kings  of  England  even  down  to  the  time  of  the  Revolution, 
because  there  were  so  many  ways  in  which  they  could  be 
utilized  to  maintain  a  position  independent  of  parliamentary 
control.  Some  of  the  kings  formed  the  practice  of  dealing 
directly  with  the  merchants  in  connection  with  customs 
matters  and  thus  obtained  an  informal  revenue  in  addition 
to  that  levied  by  law. 

From  early  times  the  right  to  levy  customs  duties  was 
used  both  by  King  and  Parliament  to  promote  home  manu- 
factures. This  use  of  the  tariff  to  regulate  commerce  and  to 
develop  home  industries  was  continued  until  well  into  the 
reign  of  Queen  Victoria,  when  the  free  trade  regime 
began. 


CROWN   REVENUES   SUBSEQUENT  TO   NORMAN    PERIOD      57 

Internal  Taxation 

The  medieval  forms  of  taxation  forecast  most  of  the 
methods  now  in  use.  There  were  poll  taxes,  a  species  of 
house  tax  called  "  hearth-money,"  land  taxes,  taxes  on 
personal  property  and  taxes  upon  income.  There  were  also 
special  taxes  upon  the  Jews  and  upon  aliens  residing  in  the 
country. 

The  land  tax  may  be  traced  back  to  feudal  times.  In  the 
very  early  days  it  was  directly  assessed  by  the  King  upon 
the  landed  proprietors.  However,  because  of  the  abuse  of 
this  right,  it  was  provided  in  Magna  Charta  that  no  scutage 
or  aid  (the  name  under  which  the  form  of  land  tax  then  levied 
was  known)  should  be  imposed  unless  with  the  consent  of  the 
Common  Council  of  the  realm,  excepting  for  ransoming  the 
King's  person,  making  his  eldest  son  a  knight,  or  marrying 
his  eldest  daughter  ;  and  even  then  only  a  reasonable  aid  was 
to  be  demanded.  In  the  course  of  time  the  land  tax  came 
to  be  included  under  the  general  name  of  subsidies. 

A  subsidy  was  properly  neither  a  tax  upon  personal  nor 
landed  property,  but  upon  income.  Every  description  of 
persons,  in  proportion  to  their  reputed  estates,  paid  after 
the  nominal  rate  of  four  shillings  in  the  pound  for  lands  and 
2s.  6d.  for  goods,  while  aliens  paid  in  a  double  proportion. 

One  of  the  earliest  forms  of  taxation  dating  from  the  reign 
of  Edward  III,  say,  from  1334,  and  in  use  until  the  time  of 
James  I  (1603-1625),  was  a  tax  on  personal  property  known 
as  "  tenths  and  fifteenths."  The  tenth  was  a  grant  laid  upon 
the  movables  or  personal  property  of  residents  of  cities  and 
towns  within  the  demesne,  and  the  fifteenth  was  a  grant 
from  the  counties  outside  the  demesne.  The  amount  for  each 
district  was  established  in  1334  and  thereafter  was  never 
changed.  Thus  each  district  knew  exactly  how  much  it  was 
expected  to  provide.  Parliament  in  making  grants  would 
specify  that  one  or  more  tenths  were  to  be  granted,  or  if  only 
a  small  sum  were  needed  half  of  a  quota  might  be  granted. 

During  the  regime  of  the  Long  Parliament  (1640-1653)  a 


58  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

form  of  taxation  was  introduced  calling  for  monthly  pay- 
ments. These  taxes  were  assessed  on  both  personal  and 
landed  property.  They  were  found  to  be  so  superior  to  the 
former  mode  of  subsidies  that  under  the  name  of  land  tax 
they  became  a  regular  method  of  taxation  in  use  for  many 
years  thereafter  and  superseded  the  old  assessments  of 
subsidies  and  tenths  and  fifteenths. 

Indirect  taxation,  except  as  exemplified  in  the  customs, 
was  unknown  in  England  until  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth 
century  when,  in  1643,  the  Long  Parliament  adopted  from 
Holland  a  system  of  excise  taxes.  This  method  of  disguised 
taxation  from  that  time  became  increasingly  popular  Avith  the 
Exchequer  Department  because  thus  it  was  possible  to  keep 
down  the  taxation  upon  the  rich  landed  classes  and  to  obtain 
what  amounted  to  a  very  heavy  tax  from  the  consumers  of 
various  articles — chiefly  beer  and  spirits,  but,  later  on,  of  tea, 
cocoa  and  other  articles — without  their  realizing  that  they 
were  paying  taxes.  As  time  went  on,  this  form  of  taxation 
was  used  on  occasion  to  regulate  the  sale  of  spirits  when  the 
Government  felt  that  their  use  was  endangering  the  moral 
status  of  the  nation.  Again,  the  finance  ministers  directly 
encouraged  the  consumption  of  spirits  in  order  that  the 
revenue  from  the  excise  might  be  increased.  To-day  this 
form  of  taxation  provides  a  very  important  portion  of  the 
revenue  of  the  State. 

The  Post  Office  dates  from  the  time  of  the  Long  Parliament, 
but  as  the  charge  for  its  services  usually  provides  very  little 
revenue  to  the  State,  the  receipts  of  this  department  can 
hardly  be  considered  a  form  of  taxation. 

Taxes  of  To-day  and  Their  Origin 

It  is  of  interest  to  run  over  the  heads  of  taxation  as  given 
in  to-day's  official  Finance  Accounts,  and  to  note  how  the 
most  important  of  these  taxes  had  their  origin  prior  to  the 
time  of  the  Revolution.  For  instance,  we  have,  in  order,  the 
Customs  dating  back  to  the  earliest  times  ;  the  Excise  dating 
back  to  the  Long  Parliament  ;    Stamps — first  introduced  in 


CROWN    REVENUES    SUBSEQUENT   TO    NORMAN    PERIOD      59 

1671 — imposed  by  a  statute  entitled  "  An  Act  for  laying 
impositions  on  proceedings  at  law."  The  Land  Tax  persists 
but  now  affords  a  very  slight  part  of  the  revenue,  although  for 
hundreds  of  years  it  was  of  great  importance.  The  House 
Duty  may  be  said  to  be  the  modern  form  of  hearth  tax,  which 
under  the  name  of  "  fumage  "  dates  back  to  Anglo-Saxon 
times.  Property  and  Income  tax — ^the  first  levy  of  a  tax 
of  this  kind — dates  back  to  the  reign  of  Richard  I  in  the  latter 
part  of  the  twelfth  century.  It  will  be  remembered  that 
upon  his  return  from  his  memorable  crusade  to  the  Holy 
I^nd,  Richard  was  captured  by  the  Emperor  of  Germany  and, 
in  order  to  effect  his  release,  was  compelled  to  pay  a  very 
heavy  ransom.  It  was  to  help  raise  the  money  for  the  pay- 
ment of  this  ransom  that  the  first  tax  in  the  nature  of  an 
income  tax  was  laid.  This  tax  was  both  an  income  tax  and 
a  personal  property  tax  and  called  for  one-quarter  of  the 
revenue  or  goods  of  every  person  in  the  realm.  The  Excess 
Profits  Duty  is  a  modern  form  of  the  income  tax.  Land 
Value  Duties  are  another  form  of  the  land  tax.  The  Post 
Office,  we  have  already  seen,  dates  from  the  time  of  the  Pro- 
tectorate. Crown  Lands,  a  prehistoric  source  of  income, 
still  figure  in  the  statement  and  actually  yield  to-day  more 
than  the  land  tax.  Thus  with  the  possible  exception  of  Estate 
Duties  only,  the  p-esent  main  forms  of  taxation  all  had  their 
origin  in  medieval  times,  or  at  least  date  from  a  time  prior 
to  the  period  of  the  Revolution  of  1688.  Even  in  the  last 
case  we  have  an  ancient  parallel  in  the  fact,  as  stated  on 
page  54,  that  estates  to  which  no  claim  could  be  made  by 
rightful  heirs  reverted  to  the  King. 

The  Church 

A  large  portion  of  the  revenues  of  the  medieval  kings  was 
drawn  from  the  Church,  which  is  stated  to  have  held  in  the 
fifteenth  century  a  fourth  of  the  landed  property  of  the  King- 
dom. Taxation  was  supplemented  by  extortion  and  finally 
in  the  reign  of  Henry  VIII  by  the  wholesale  confiscation  of 
Church  properties. 


60  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

Extortions 

We  have  now  reviewed  the  regular  sources  of  Crown 
income.  The  pre-Revolution  sovereigns  were  perpetually 
living  beyond  their  income  and  frequently  were  at  swords' 
points  with  Parliament.  Therefore  they  exercised  their 
ingenuity  to  discover  means  of  meeting  their  expenses  without 
going  to  Parliament.  To  this  end  they  pushed  their  preroga- 
tive rights  to  great  extremes.  By  collusion  with  the  judges 
they  punished  infractions  of  the  laws  with  severe  fines.  As 
stated  above,  they  made  levies  on  the  religious  orders  and  upon 
the  Church,  and  Henry  VIII  confiscated  Church  properties. 
They  made  forced  loans  from  their  subjects  of  high  and  low 
degree  which  they  forgot  to  pay.  They  created  new  orders  of 
nobility  for  initiation  into  which  they  made  heavy  charges. 
They  went  around  among  their  subjects  almost  hat  in  hand 
asking  for  gifts — "  benevolences,"  they  were  called.  They 
granted  licences  for  various  acts.  They  engaged  in  business 
enterprises  and  had  part  interests  in  privateering  expeditions. 
Then  there  was  the  loot  and  the  spoil  of  the  wars  in  which 
most  of  them  engaged.  One  favourite  method  of  supplying 
national  requirements  and  of  filling  his  private  purse  was  for 
the  King  to  grant  the  right  to  monopolize  certain  lines  of 
manufacture  or  of  business  and  finally,  if  all  else  failed,  the 
coinage  might  be  debased  and  the  seigniorage  realized. 

Coinage 

The  first  debasement  of  the  coinage  recorded  is  in  the 
reign  of  Edward  I  when,  in  the  year  1300,  the  penny  was 
reduced  one-half  grain  in  weight,  so  that  243  pennies,  instead 
of  240  as  before,  were  struck  from  a  pound  of  silver.  In  1344 
and  again  in  1346  the  standard  was  further  lowered,  raising 
the  number  of  pennies  in  the  pound  to  270.  In  the  reign  of 
Edward  IV,  in  1464  and  1465,  the  number  of  pennies  to  the 
pound  was  raised  to  450.  Henry  VIII  and  Edward  VI 
debased  the  coins  several  times,  so  that  in  the  latter's  reign 
the  silver  coins  contained  only  one-seventh  of  the  pure  metal 
that  went  to  the  same  coins  of  25  years  before. 


CROWN   REVENUES   SUBSEQUENT  TO   NORALA.N   PERIOD     61 

One  of  the  notable  events  of  Elizabeth's  reign  was  the 
restoration  of  the  coinage.  This  she  arranged  before  she 
had  been  two  years  on  the  throne.  It  is  said  to  have  been 
necessary  for  her  to  borrow  two  hundred  thousand  pounds 
from  the  city  of  Antwerp  in  order  to  carry  through  this 
reform.  Even  Elizabeth,  with  all  her  inherent  love  for 
financial  honesty,  was  prevailed  upon  to  have  a  base  coinage 
struck  for  use  in  Ireland,  while  in  the  forty-third  year  of  her 
reign  she  was  persuaded  to  have  sixty-two  instead  of  sixty 
shillings  minted  from  the  pound  of  silver.  Since  the  reign 
of  Elizabeth  no  sovereign  has  ever  attempted  to  debase  the 
coin  of  the  realm.  However,  through  sweating  and  clipping, 
the  coinage  had  become  so  debased  at  the  time  of  the  Revolu- 
tion that  in  1696  William  HI  was  compelled  to  take  steps 
for  its  restoration. 


CHAPTER   XI 

CROWN   DEBTS 

(1216-1688) 
Henry  HI  (1216-1272)  is  the  first  king  of  England  whose 
debts  are  recorded  in  history.  In  the  16th  year  of  his  reign 
they  had  become  so  great  that  Parliament  was  obliged  to 
grant  an  "  aid  " — that  is,  a  tax — to  assist  him  in  paying  them 
off.  He  is  said  to  have  pawned  the  jewels  of  the  crown, 
his  robes  of  state  and  other  royal  ornaments,  and  even  the 
shrine  of  St.  Edward.  Matthew  Paris,  the  chronicler  of  this 
period,  states  that  he  owed  so  much  to  so  many  different 
people,  for  the  very  necessities  of  life,  that  "  he  durst  hardly 
appear  in  public  for  the  clamour  of  his  creditors."  Henry 
borrowed  from  the  Italian  merchants,  from  the  Jews,  from 
his  own  brother — in  fact,  when  and  where  he  could. 

Interest  Payments  Forbidden 

The  sentiment  of  the  time  was  strongly  against  the  pay- 
ment of  interest,  or  "  usury,"  as  it  was  called  ;  in  fact,  such 
payments  were  interdict  by  the  Church.  However,  in  case 
of  the  non-payment  of  a  loan  when  due,  a  charge  could  be 
made  for  the  inconvenience  to  which  the  lender  had  been 
subjected  by  such  delay.  Such  charges  sometimes  ran  as 
high  as  10  per  cent,  a  month. 

Thereafter  scarcely  a  reign  passed  without  borrowing  to  a 
larger  or  smaller  extent.  If  these  debts  were  not  liquidated 
within  the  reign  they  were  usually  honoured  by  the  succeeding 
monarch.  Fortunately  for  the  lenders  there  was  a  supersti- 
tion that  until  the  debts  of  the  deceased  were  paid  his  soul 
would  remain  in  purgatory.  Therefore  it  was  a  filial  duty 
for  a  son  to  provide  for  his  father's  obligations. 

Security  Given 

These  loans  were  sometimes  raised  upon  the  security  of 
the  customs.     Sometimes  the  customs  were    "  fa^^med  "    or 

62 


CROWN    DEBTS  63 

sold  to  foreign  money  lenders  for  a  lump  sum  or  for  an  agreed 
periodical  payment.  The  farmer,  as  his  profit,  retained  any 
amount  collected  above  the  agreed  payment. 

Towards  the  end  of  the  reign  of  the  fifth  Henry,  we  find  a 
new  precedent  being  established  in  regard  to  Crown  debts. 
This  occurred  in  1421,  upon  the  return  of  the  King  from  a 
successful  campaign  against  the  French.  The  King  had 
incurred  heavy  debts  for  the  payment  of  which  Parliament 
authorized  security  to  be  given  in  the  form  of  letters  patent 
to  the  lenders  that  they  would  be  paid  out  of  the  first  produce 
of  a  subsidy,  a  new  tax  of  the  nature  of  an  income  tax,  which 
was  granted  at  the  same  time  and  which  we  have  already 
described.  The  fact  that  this  tax  did  not  prove  to  be  suffi.- 
cient  for  the  purpose  and  that  in  the  end  the  King  was  com- 
pelled to  pledge  the  royal  crown  and  jewels  to  make  up  the 
deficiency  does  not  alter  the  significance  of  this  action. 

Repudiation  of  Debts  by  Henry  VIII 

Henry  VIII,  among  other  infractions  of  the  laws  of  God 
and  the  rights  of  his  subjects  with  which  he  was  justly  charge- 
able, was  also  guilty  of  repudiating  his  debts.  The  Parliament 
of  1525  which  impeached  Wolsey  passed  an  extraordinary 
statute  wherein  "  they  do,  for  themselves  and  all  the  whole 
body  of  the  realm  which  they  represent,  freely,  liberally 
and  absolutely,  give  and  grant  unto  the  King's  highness, 
by  authority  of  this  present  Parliament,  all  and  every  sum 
and  sums  of  money  which  to  them  and  every  of  them,  is, 
ought  or  might  be  due,  by  reason  of  any  money  or  of  any 
other  thing,  to  his  grace  at  any  time  heretofore  advanced 
or  paid  by  way  of  trust  or  loan,  either  upon  any  letter  or 
letters  under  the  King's  privy  seal,  general  or  particular, 
letter,  missive,  promise,  bond,  or  obligation  of  repayment 
or  by  any  taxation  or  other  assessing,  by  virtue  of  any  com- 
mission or  commissions,  or  by  any  other  mean  or  means, 
whatever  it  be,  heretofore  passed  for  that  purpose."  This 
action  naturally  excited  much  resentment  and  worked  hard- 
ship to  many,  as  it  converted  loans  into  taxes  because  the 


EXGUSH  FCVUC  FTXAXVIZ 


Ac  TTftaxnat  of  ^lAicii  mas  refosed.  \ 
OLiuiteil  fcoB  Ae  kados^  exactlj^  a 
taken  m  tbe  farm  of  taxes.  On  tbe  otbcr 
ihut  vcre  nsuny  vibo  mere  pleased  to  see  Wofenr's 
far  tkey  mere  tke  |a  aw  i|Ml  cxcdUcKS^  amexcedp  aad  tke 
Kii^s  debts  iiiiiiiiifcflni  i1  Ibe  finem^  of  tke  pcofie  mere 
^ad  that  a  Mode  of  sa|iistv  so  daageroos  to  pohic  Hbcrty 
be  dbuedUcd.  Uns  bad  pnecedeal  mas  fiiliiwiri 
a  1544.  lAea  a  sinibr  act  mas  passed  rdeasiae  tke 
Sjb^  fraaa  al  moory  bcsramed  aoce  15^  and.  laewei. 
reqnaig  tkose  adu  had  leieiied  any  payments  oa  atecmat 
of  sack  kaas  to  rcfand  tke  WMmef  to  lAe  Treasmy . 


\"in 


VI  and  of  Hoy  k 
aas  on  tke  Cootinfm. 

-  -T^.     A?  bSc?!  as  14  OCT  ceat. 


Hamboif:,  Ookene  and 
'-  ^om  10 percent,  to 


:v  of 


CRO\^'N   DEBTS  65 

Finally,  by  frugality  and  good  management,  she  procured  the 
money  at  home  to  liquidate  entirely  her  foreign  debt. 

Stop  of  the  Exchequer 

The  Stuarts  were  also  hea\y  borrowers,  while  to  the  discredit 
of  Charles  II  is  the  fact  that  in  1672  he  stopped  the  repa^-ment 
of  loans  made  by  the  Goldsmiths  to  the  Exchequer.  He 
thus  tied  up  their  resources  and  ruined  many  of  them  and, 
in  turn,  their  clients  whose  bankers  they  were.  This  debt 
was  finally  compromised  late  in  the  reign  of  William  III 
at  ten  shillings  on  the  pound.  This  is  the  famous  "  Stop  of 
the  Exchequer." 

All  in  all,  the  hist  on,-  of  Crown  borrowing  is  not  a  very 
creditable  one.  It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  in  these 
early  days  there  \^-as  no  such  thing  as  a  national  debt.  The 
lenders  dealt  with  the  King  very  much  as  they  would  with  a 
private  indi\iduaL  As,  for  a  large  part  of  this  period,  the 
pa^Tnent  of  interest  was  regarded  as  an  irreligious  act,  many 
subterfuges  were  resoned  to  in  order  that  the  lender  might 
be  compensated  for  his  risk  and  the  use  of  his  capital.  One 
arrangement  was  that  a  charge  might  be  made  for  delayed 
pa\Tnent5  ;  therefore  it  was  customary  to  allow  a  loan  to 
mature  and  then  to  run  along  for  a  longer  or  shorter  period 
thereafter.  The  money  lenders  sometimes  received  a  per- 
centage on  the  taxes  collected  b}-  acting  as  farmers  of  the 
revenue  as  already  explained.  Sometimes  the  lenders  were 
rewarded  with  gifts  of  titles,  or  lands  or  jewels. 


5— (182S) 


CHAPTER  XII 

CONSTITUTIONAL  GOVERNMENT   DEVELOPED   BY  CONTROL 
OF   PURSE 

(1066-1688) 

England's  present  democratic  form  of  government  has 
been  developed  from  the  autocracy  of  the  Middle  Ages  by 
a  gradual  process  of  evolution. 

The  Plantagenets 

Magna  Charta  extorted  by  the  barons  from  King  John  in 
1215  remedied  certain  feudal  abuses  in  the  matters  of  pur- 
veyance, relief,  wardship  and  marriage  and  in  particular 
admitted  the  right  of  the  nation  to  ordain  taxation  and  defined 
the  way  in  which  its  consent  was  to  be  given. 

Before  1295  when  arranging  for  grants  it  was  customary 
for  the  King  to  deal  separately  with  the  clergy  and  the  barons. 
In  this  year,  in  the  reign  of  Edward  I,  a  transition  which  had 
been  gradually  taking  place  since  1282  took  fixed  form  and 
the  Commons  were  admitted  to  a  share  of  the  taxing  power. 
The  three  estates  acted  separately  and  made  grants  of  varying 
amounts,  but  they  took  action  simultaneously  at  a  common 
place  of  meeting.  The  year  1303  is  memorable  in  commercial 
as  well  as  constitutional  history.  It  was  in  this  year  that 
the  Charta  Mercatoria  was  granted.  This  has  been  called 
the  Magna  Charta  of  Commerce.  By  its  terms  the  ports, 
cities  and  towns  of  England  were  opened  for  wholesale  traffic 
to  foreign  merchants. 

The  codification  of  the  laws  under  this  King  and  the 
revision  of  the  charters  all  tended  to  strengthen  the  position 
of  the  people. 

The  necessities  of  Edward  III  and  the  weakness  of  Richard 
II  still  more  strengthened  the  position  of  the  people,  so 
that  they  did  not  hesitate  to  depose  Richard  in  favour  of  a 
king  who  it  was  thought  would  reign  more  equitably,  but 

66 


CONSTITUTIONAL  GOVERNMENT  67 

while  conditions  then  were  not  dissimilar  to  those  subse- 
quently, at  the  time  when  James  II  was  deposed,  the  people 
were  not  yet  ready  to  take  advantage  of  the  progress  they 
had  made.  The  King  was  still  an  autocrat  and  would  be 
for  several  centuries,  but  the  right  of  the  taxpayer  to  be  heard 
before  he  backed  up  the  King's  projects  with  his  aid  was 
coming  to  be  fully  recognized,  although  the  King  constantly 
endeavoured  to  evade  that  condition,  only  to  be  brought  to 
book  again  when  some  critical  situation,  such  as  a  foreign  war, 
requiring  large  contributions,  should  arise.  But  it  took 
several  centuries  more  of  experience  before  the  people  were 
prepared  for  self-government. 

Lancaster  and  York 

The  six  reigns  of  the  Lancastrian  and  Yorkist  kings  covering 
the  greater  part  of  the  fifteenth  century  (1399  to  1485)  were 
years  of  foreign  wars  and  domestic  strife.  During  the  reigns 
of  the  Lancastrian  Henrys,  constitutional  forms  were  well 
observed.  This  period  of  about  sixty  years  was  one  of 
poverty  on  the  part  of  the  Crown  when  large  dependence 
must  be  placed  upon  parliamentary  grants.  On  this  account 
Parliament  became  much  bolder  than  in  previous  reigns. 
It  did  not  hesitate  to  interfere  with  the  management  of  the 
King's  household,  by  urging  economy  in  household  expendi- 
tures and  limiting  the  purposes  for  which  such  expenditures 
might  be  made. 

It  was  during  the  reign  of  Henry  IV  that  the  right  of  the 
Commons  to  initiate  money  legislation  was  brought  to  the 
fore  and  the  precedent  in  that  respect  more  firmly  established. 

The  Tudors 

The  Tudor  period  (1485-1603)  was  one  of  reaction.  The 
people  to  a  great  extent  lost  control  of  the  Crown.  For 
the  most  part  parliamentary  forms  were  observed  and  the 
checks  to  royal  authority  which  had  been  gradually  developed 
from  the  time  of  Norman  William  were  not  directly 
contravened  but  more  than  once  they  were  evaded. 


68  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

The  customary  grants  of  revenue  by  votes  of  Parliament 
were  made  at  irregular  periods  and  it  is  known  that  the 
revenue  from  such  sources  was  relatively  unimportant  in 
comparison  with  that  derived  from  the  customs,  from  the 
King's  prerogative  and  from  compulsive  and  voluntary  loans, 
and  during  the  reigns  of  Henry  VIII  and  Edward  VI  from  the 
debasement  of  the  coinage  and  the  sales  of  the  confiscated 
church  lands.  In  other  words,  the  sovereigns  of  this  period 
found  ways  and  means  to  get  along  with  small  parliamentary 
grants  and  therefore  could  be  as  autocratic  as  their  fellow 
monarchs  across  seas  while  yet  keeping  up  the  appearance  of 
subserviency  to  old  constitutional  forms. 

The  Stuarts 

The  period  of  English  history  lying  between  the  reign  of 
Elizabeth  and  the  Revolution  (1603-1688)  is  distinctive  as 
the  one  in  which  the  powers  of  sovereignty  are  finally  trans- 
ferred from  the  Crown  to  Parliament.  After  the  close  of  the 
seventeenth  century  we  no  longer  speak  of  Crown  finance 
but  of  national  finance.  While  all  other  peoples,  with  the 
exception  only  of  the  Swiss,  were  giving  up  all  rights  of 
citizenship  to  autocrats  of  the  most  absolute  type,  England 
was  evolving  a  system  of  government  which  combined 
"  freedom  with  efficiency,  and  local  rights  with  national 
union." 

These  changes  did  not  take  place  hastily — in  fact,  English 
life  in  all  departments  of  activity  was  essentially  the  same, 
so  far  as  surface  indications  went,  in  the  times  of  the  first 
Scotch  kings,  as  it  was  during  Elizabethan  times.  Political 
events  of  great  importance  were  gradually  shaping  men's 
minds  for  the  radical  changes  of  the  latter  part  of  the  period — 
from  1640  on. 

The  Stuarts  had  all  the  Tudor  love  of  power  and  belief 
in  the  inherent  rights  of  monarchs  to  rule,  without  the  Tudor 
ability  to  manage  their  subjects. 

James  I  did  not  know  anything,  either  in  the  spirit  or  in 
the  letter,  about  the  laws  and  liberties  peculiar  to  England. 


CONSTITUTIONAL   GOVERNMENT  69 

Constitutional  custom  and  parliamentary  privilege  meant 
nothing  to  him  until  late  in  life  and  then  he  looked  upon  them 
solely  as  an  impediment  to  a  benevolent  government.  Eliza- 
beth by  her  economies  had  put  the  finances  of  the  nation  on 
a  sound  basis  and  had  left  the  Treasury  in  a  flourishing 
condition.  However,  James  spent  money  so  freely  that  he 
was  in  constant  need  and  thus  was  continually  in  opposition  to 
Parliament.  Early  in  his  reign  he  revived  the  feudal  rights 
of  the  King  to  collect  revenue  independent  of  parliamentary 
grants.  A  vigorous  controversy  arose  over  these  efforts  of 
the  King.  A  compromise  was  proposed  in  the  form  of  a 
contract  to  be  entered  into  by  the  Crown  with  ParHament, 
whereby  in  consideration  of  a  grant  for  life  of  ^^200,000  a 
year  the  King  would  surrender  all  sources  of  revenue  due  to 
his  prerogative.  The  consummation  of  this  plan  was  pre- 
vented by  religious  controversies  which  led  to  the  dissolution 
of  Parliament  in  February,  1611. 

From  this  time  until  January,  1621,  a  period  of  ten  years, 
the  King  reigned  without  parliamentary  co-operation  except 
for  a  two  months  meeting  of  the  "  Addled  Parliament  "  in 
1614.     Court  intrigue  dominated  public  affairs  for  this  decade. 

Finally,  the  approach  of  war  abroad  made  it  necessary  in 
1621  to  call  a  Parliament,  and  for  a  few  years  the  parliamentary 
side  was  temporarily  in  the  ascendency, 

Charles  I  succeeded  to  the  throne  in  1625  and  for  eleven 
years  conducted  the  affairs  of  the  nation  without  the  aid  or 
interference  of  Parliament.  Then  the  pent-up  forces  of 
democracy  broke  loose,  assuring  to  England  and  the  English- 
speaking  world  the  ascendency  of  the  principles  of 
representative  government. 

Commonwealth  and  Protectorate 

The  period  from  the  death  of  Charles  I  to  the  accession 
of  Charles  II  (1649-1660)  is  called  by  some  historians  the 
period  of  the  Republic.  Nothing  could  be  further  from  the 
modern  conception  of  a  republican  form  of  government — 
that  is   of  a  government  founded  upon  representation.     The 


70  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

government  of  Cromwell  was  dependent  for  its  power 
upon  his  army  and  he  dare  not  appeal  to  the  voters  except 
in  a  partial  and  negative  way.  As  Trevelyan  says  :  "  When 
the  roundheads  in  the  name  of  the  people  had  seized  power 
they  found  not  only  the  active  champions  of  democracy 
but  the  people  itself — whatever  definition  be  given  to  that 
term — bitterly  hostile  to  their  rule." 

Nevertheless  the  period  was  one  of  active  training  of  the 
people  for  self-rule.  The  naval  supremacy  of  Great  Britain 
was  then  firmly  established  and  the  path  of  Empire  blazed 
and  its  foundation  laid. 

Public  discussion  which  under  James  had  been  frowned 
upon  and  under  Charles  actively  repressed  was  free  and 
open  after  the  war  broke  out  between  King  and  Parliament. 
The  period  was  one  which  compelled  men  to  think  hard 
and  to  take  definite  positions,  for  which  they  must  be  prepared 
to  give  their  reasons  and  to  stake  their  lives  and  fortunes. 

Under  the  Commonwealth  and  the  Protectorate  the  cost 
of  government  was  the  highest  which  the  country  had  ever 
known.  However,  this  increased  cost  was  part  of  the  disci- 
pline which  the  country  needed  to  prepare  it  eventually  for 
self-government.  Still  this  does  not  change  the  fact  that 
the  Protectorate  was  thereby  brought  to  its  end  and  the 
restoration  of  the  monarchy  made  popular. 

The  pressure  of  taxes,  the  general  depression  of  trade, 
the  poverty  and  suffering  of  the  working  classes  and  the  bad 
state  of  credit  all  combined  to  make  the  people  ready  for  a 
change.  So,  when  the  guiding  hand  of  the  great  Cromwell 
was  removed  by  death,  his  government  easily  disintegrated 
and  once  more  a  king  took  his  place  at  the  head  of  affairs. 

Charles  II 

The  restoration  of  the  monarchy  seemed  to  be  necessary 
to  prevent  civil  war.  It  was  the  only  form  of  government 
upon  which  all  parties  could  agree.  The  country  was  to 
endure  for  almost  a  generation  the  rule  of  the  profligate 
Charles  II  and  the  bigoted  James  II.     During  this  period  the 


CONSTITUTIONAL  GOVERNMENT  71 

forces  making  for  constitutional  government  were  still  further 
developing  to  come  to  their  fruition  in  1688  through  a  final 
revolution. 

Now  that  government  had  resumed  its  normal  course  the 
traditional  policy  of  the  nation  against  the  maintenance  of  a 
standing  army  led,  as  a  first  step,  to  the  disbandment  of  the 
army.  As  the  pay  of  the  soldiers  was  much  in  arrears  it  was 
necessary  to  raise  at  once  for  this  purpose  the  sum  of  around 
£400,000.  This  was  accomplished  by  the  imposition  of  a 
graduated  poll-tax,  said  to  have  been  up  to  that  time  "  the 
greatest  poll-tax,  and  most  particular,  that  had  been  known." 
No  one  was  overlooked,  from  the  nobility  to  the  humblest 
citizen.  The  charges  ranged  from  £100  for  a  duke  to  sixpence 
for  "  every  person  not  rated,  nor  receiving  alms,  above 
sixteen  years  of  age."  By  reading  this  Act  one  may  cause 
to  pass  in  review  representatives  of  every  class  in  the  social 
life  of  the  time — dukes,  marquises,  earls,  viscounts,  barons, 
baronets,  knights,  sergeants-at-law,  esquires,  parsons,  vicars, 
doctors  of  the  civil  or  canon  law,  doctors  of  physic  ;  mayors, 
sheriffs,  aldermen,  town  clerks  ;  masters  and  other  officers 
of  the  livery  companies  ;  dyers,  brewers,  leather-followers, 
girdlers,  apothecaries,  tallow-chandlers  and  others.  Then 
there  were  the  barber-surgeons,  the  white-bakers,  the  brown- 
bakers,  butchers,  carpenters  and  other  tradesmen.  Then  a 
long  list  of  those  in  mechanical  pursuits  and  the  building 
trades.  The  courts'  officers  and  clerks  and  the  officers  and 
clerks  of  the  other  departments  of  the  Government  all  had  to 
pay,  and  finally,  to  sweep  in  any  who  might  have  been  over- 
looked, "  everyone  that  could  spend,  in  land,  lease,  moneys  or 
stock,  £100  per  annum,  40  shillings,  and  so  on  for  a  greater 
or  ^ess  estate."  The  produce  of  this  tax  is  not  reported,  but 
it  is  recorded  that  the  much  dreaded  army  merged  with  the 
rest  of  the  population  and  was  quickly  a  thing  of  the  past. 
The  King  retained  about  5,000  men  under  arms,  thus  laying 
the  foundation  for  a  moderate  standing  army  such  as  England 
has  since  then  maintained.  Pending  the  collection  of  this 
tax  and  of  a  special  assessment   on  lands  and  movables. 


72  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

arrangements  were  made  with  the  city  of  London  for  a  loan. 
Charles  was  successful  in  inducing  Parliament  to  settle  a 
permanent  revenue  upon  him  of  £1,200,000  a  year.  This 
was  something  many  times  before  attempted  but  now  for  the 
first  time  arranged.  The  King  was  to  surrender  all  revenues 
from  his  prerogative,  such  as  wardships,  marriages,  purvey- 
ance, pre-emption  and  the  like,  from  which  a  considerable 
portion  of  the  Crown  income  had  previously  been  obtained. 
On  the  other  hand.  Parliament  made  the  new  appropriation  a 
special  charge  upon  an  excise  tax  upon  Hquors,  including  not 
only  beer,  ale,  cyder,  strong-water,  but  also  vinegar  and  even 
coffee,  chocolate,  sherbet  and  tea.  The  income  from  this 
source  not  proving  to  be  sufficient  to  produce  the  amount 
appropriated,  it  was  later  found  necessary  to  supplement  it  by 
other  taxes. 

The  remainder  of  this  reign  was  marked  by  continued 
clashes  between  King  and  Parliament.  Large  supplies  were 
required  for  the  conduct  of  wars  with  the  Dutch. 

For  the  expenses  of  the  first  war  Parliament  readily  voted 
the  requisite  amount.  Two  notable  departures  were  made 
from  former  usage.  The  old  method  of  raising  money  by 
subsidies  of  tenths  and  fifteenths  was  abandoned  for  ever 
and  the  mode  of  monthly  assessments  introduced  during 
the  Civil  War  adopted  instead.  The  clergy  who  used  to 
tax  themselves  in  convocation  now  consented  to  be  taxed  by 
Parliament  in  the  same  manner  as  the  laity.  In  return  they 
obtained  the  right  of  voting  at  elections. 

This  war  with  its  disgraceful  ending,  the  fire  of  London 
and  the  plague,  all  combined  to  make  the  people  restive  under 
the  necessarily  heavy  taxation  while  their  incomes  were 
seriously  curtailed. 

So,  when  Charles  in  1672  secretly  began  another  war 
against  HoUand,  without  the  consent  of  Parliament,  he 
obtained  the  cash  resources  required  by  confiscating  the 
balances  of  the  merchants  loaned  to  the  Exchequer.  This  vas 
the  "  Stop  of  the  Exchequer  "  already  considered.  This  is 
the  last  instance  in  English  history  of  such  a  proceeding,  just 


CONSTITUTIONAL   GOVERNMENT  73 

as  the  Stuarts  were  the  last  of  the  autocratic  sovereigns. 
Parliament  finally  forced  peace  in  1674  by  refusing  to  give 
further  supplies.  Just  as  it  seemed  as  if  Parliament  had  the 
King  in  a  position  where  he  must  abandon  his  autocratic 
methods  he  succeeded  in  obtaining  a  loan  from  Louis  of 
France  and  Parliament  did  not  meet  again  during  the  last 
four  years  of  his  reign  which  ended  in  February,  1685, 

James  II 

Upon  his  accession  James  II  was  apparently  one  of  the 
most  autocratic  of  rulers.  The  people  were  subservient  and 
Parliament  voted  him  large  supplies  for  life.  He  had  a  large 
army,  although  it  was  not  well  disciplined  and  was  not  in 
sympathy  with  his  religious  views.  However,  while  the 
nation  was  much  divided  on  the  subject  of  religion  and  one 
Protestant  sect  was  cruelly  treating  all  the  others,  they  were 
a  unit  in  opposing  his  desire  for  Catholic  supremacy.  Thus 
the  nation  was  prepared  to  take  the  stand  against  James 
which  was  involved  in  asking  William  the  Hollander  to  head 
an  armed  expedition  to  England.  And  so  with  the  flight  of 
James  to  France  ended  the  Stuart  dynasty  and  autocracy. 


CHAPTER  XIII 

ENGLAND  AFTER  THE   REVOLUTION   OF    1688 

(1688-1920) 

The  Revolution  of  1688  drew  a  sharp  line  between  old 
England  and  an  England  in  which  new  conditions  were  to 
prevail.  In  politics,  in  its  economic  status,  in  its  outlook 
upon  the  rest  of  the  world  and  its  relations  therewith,  the 
nation  was  to  experience  changes  of  the  greatest  importance 
to  the  welfare  of  its  people. 

The  history  of  this  new  England  naturally  divides  into 
three  epochal  periods.  First  we  have  a  century  and  a  third 
in  which  the  keynote  is  war — war  in  a  military  sense  ;  war  in 
an  economic  sense.  England  for  the  English  and  England 
against  the  world,  including  her  own  colonies  and  her  sister 
island  of  Ireland. 

The  dominating  note  of  the  next  century  is  peace,  accom- 
panied by  great  political,  industrial,  economic  and  social 
changes. 

Then  we  have  the  brief  climateric  period  of  the  recent 
war — a  period  when  England  nobly  and  voluntarily  supported 
by  all  her  Dominions  and  Dependencies  ;  joined  hands 
with  France,  Italy,  America  and  other  allies,  to  save  from 
destruction  their  common  civilization. 

Origin  of  the  National  Debt 

The  great  financial  engines  which  provided  the  power  to 
make  this  victory  possible  had  their  genesis  during  the  closing 
years  of  the  seventeenth  century.  The  ideas  which  gave 
them  birth  were  probably  of  Dutch  origin,  brought  with  him 
from  Holland  by  William  III.  These  were  public  borrowing 
and  banking.  Prior  to  1688  there  had  been  no  such  thing 
in  England  as  a  national  debt.  The  sovereigns  had  frequently 
borrowed  money  but  these  loans  were  transactions  with 
special  groups  of  moneyed  men  and  in  no  sense  borrowings 

74 


ENGLAND  AFTER  THE  REVOLUTION   OF    1688  75 

of  a  national  character,  raised  on  a  systematic  basis.  As 
an  alien,  King  William  hesitated  to  burden  the  people  too 
heavily  with  taxation  and  therefore  to  meet  the  expense  of 
his  wars  resorted  to  borrowing  on  a  large  scale. 

The  Bank  of  England 

In  1694  the  Bank  of  England  was  incorporated. 

This  was  the  first  incorporated  banking  institution  in 
England.  Its  charter,  which  was  granted  24th  July,  1694, 
provided  that  in  exchange  for  a  loan  to  the  Exchequer  of 
£1,200,000  the  incorporators  might  deal  in  bullion  and  bills 
of  exchange,  issue  notes  and  make  advances  on  merchandise. 
It  was  a  private  undertaking  and  so  remains  to  the  present  day. 
On  the  other  hand,  it  performs  important  public  functions, 
such  as  the  management  of  the  public  debt  and  finances. 
Its  history,  privileges  and  responsibilities  are  discussed  in 
detail  in  subsequent  pages. 

The  Exchequer,  or  Treasury,  Bill 

The  first  Exchequer  bills  were  issued  in  1696.  As  originally 
issued  they  were  a  form  of  Government  currency. 

Their  subsequent  use  has  been  to  bridge  over  the  period 
between  expenditure  and  the  receipt  of  income  from  taxation 
or  from  long  time  loans.  They  have  served  as  the  shuttle 
which  wove  into  the  fabric  of  Government  resources  the 
floating  capital  of  the  realm.  Since  1877  Treasury  Bills 
which  perform  the  same  functions  have  taken  their  place. 
The  principal  difference  between  these  two  classes  of  bills 
is  that  the  Exchequer  bills  were  paid  with  accrued  interest 
while  Treasury  bills  are  issued  at  a  discount  and  paid  off  at 
par. 

The  Income  Tax 

Another  mighty  engine  of  public  finance,  the  income  tax 
in  its  modern  form,  was  not  provided  until  late  in  the  next 
century.  This  tax  was  first  levied  in  1799  at  the  instance  of 
William  Pitt,  the  younger,  as  an  aid  in  the  financing  of  the 


76  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

first  part  of  the  Great  French  War.  It  was  levied  at  the  rate 
of  10  per  cent,  on  all  incomes  of  two  hundred  pounds  and 
above.  In  the  first  full  year  of  its  operation  it  provided  about 
four  and  a  half  million.  Compare  this,  even  after  making 
liberal  allowance  for  the  greater  purchasing  power  of  the  £ 
sterling  in  Pitt's  time,  with  the  return  of  the  last  fiscal  year 
(1919-1920)  of  nearly  three  hundred  and  sixty  million,  or, 
with  excess  profits  tax  added,  some  six  hundred  and  fifty 
million.  Its  prototype,  first  levied  in  the  reign  of  Richard  I, 
may  have  yielded  forty  thousand  pounds — exact  figures  are 
not  available. 

Joint-Stock  Banking 

Then,  in  this  survey,  we  must  not  overlook  the  importance 
of  the  introduction  of  joint-stock  banking  in  England  in  1826, 
and  the  extension  of  the  privileges  of  such  banks  to  the  City 
of  London  in  1833.  The  marshalling  of  the  credit  resources 
of  the  world  through  the  agency  of  these  banks  and  of  the 
great  acceptance  houses  made  England  the  financial  clearing 
house  for  the  world's  trade.  Thus  there  were  concentrated 
in  London  great  reservoirs  of  credit  which  made  it  possible 
for  England  to  carry  so  heavy  a  part  of  the  financial  burden 
of  the  recent  war.  The  combined  financial  resources  of 
England  and  America  mobilized  through  their  private  cor- 
porate banks  and  their  respective  semi-state  banks,  and  Bank 
of  England  and  the  Federal  Reserve  System,  provided  the 
credit  resources  without  the  use  of  which  the  war  could  not 
have  been  fought  to  its  successful  climax. 

Public  Expenditure 

We  may  now  turn  to  a  consideration  of  the  uses  to  which 
moneys  were  put  which  were  made  available  by  this  financial 
machinery  of  taxation,  borrowing  and  banking.  We  find  in 
the  requirements  of  war  the  greatest  cause  of  the  creation 
and  growth  of  public  debt.  War,  the  preparation  for  war, 
the  aftermath  of  war  in  the  form  of  pensions  and  the  interest 
upon  the  public  debt,  accounts  for  over  85  per  cent,  of  the 


ENGLAND  AFTER  THE   REVOLUTION   OF   1688  77 

total  expenditure  of  the  nation  from  the  Revolution  until 
the  present  time.  In  this  connection  the  tables  of  expenditure 
and  of  income  from  1688-1920  printed  with  Chapter  XXV 
will  be  found  worthy  of  special  study. 

The  Tariff 

Finally,  we  may  consider  the  use  of  the  taxing  power  for 
other  purposes  than  to  produce  income.  Until  1842  England 
possessed  a  highly  protective  tariff,  designed  to  promote  the 
interests  of  the  land  owners  and  the  manufacturers.  Up  to 
that  time  the  customs  tariffs  were  devised  both  with  a  view 
to  giving  this  protection  and  to  obtaining  revenue.  This 
was  also  true  of  some  internal  taxation.  In  1846,  largely  as  a 
sequence  to  the  Irish  famine  of  1845,  the  corn  laws  were 
repealed.  Thereafter  the  other  protective  duties  were 
gradually  removed,  so  that,  since  1866,  England  has  enjoyed 
absolute  free  trade. 

England  in  1914 

At  the  time  of  the  outbreak  of  the  recent  war  England 
was  the  richest  of  the  nations,  so  far  as  developed  resources 
were  concerned.  Her  commerce  was  world-wide,  her  manu- 
factures went  everywhere,  carried  for  the  most  part  by  her 
own  ships.  These  also  carried  a  large  percentage  of  the 
goods  of  other  nations,  especially  foodstuffs  for  home  con- 
sumption and  the  raw  materials  of  manufacture  for  which 
England  is  dependent  upon  the  rest  of  the  world.  England 
in  1914  was  the  world's  banker  and  her  capital  was  invested 
in  the  promotion  of  industry  and  transportation  not  only  at 
home  and  in  her  own  colonial  possessions,  but  in  many  other 
countries,  especially  in  the  Americas. 

The  Future  ? 

The  recent  war  has  brought  about  important  changes  in 
all  of  these  relations.  It  is  too  soon  as  yet  to  determine  to 
what  these  changes  will  lead.  Much  depends  upon  the 
Enghsh  working-man  and  working-woman.     By  the  progress 


78  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

of  events  he  and  she  have  now  largely  devolved  upon  them 
the  decision  as  to  what  shall  be  the  future  history  of  the 
nation.  For  good  or  ill  over  the  centuries,  slowly,  almost 
imperceptibly  at  first,  but  finally  with  great  rapidity  within 
the  last  fifty  years,  this  power  has  come  to  them. 


i 


CHAPTER  XIV 

WAR  AND   DEBT 
(1688-1817) 

The  period  of  English  history  extending  from  the  accession 
of  William  III  to  the  close  of  the  Napoleonic  wars  was  one 
marked  by  a  succession  of  wars  and  a  steady  growth  of  debt. 

In  1688  the  only  debt  of  the  nation  consisted  of  some 
£384,000  of  temporary  obligations  for  arrears  due  to  the 
army  and  for  other  demands  arising  from  the  Revolution. 
There  was  also  in  litigation  the  claim  of  the  Goldsmiths  for 
reimbursement  of  the  amounts  seized  from  them  by  Charles  II 
at  the  time  of  the  "  Stop  of  the  Exchequer  "  in  1672.  This 
claim  was  later  adjudicated  at  ^^664,263.  So  the  entire 
debt  as  of  1688  was  a  little  over  one  million  pounds. 

In  the  century  and  a  third  lying  between  this  date  and 
1817,  when  the  expenses  of  the  Great  French  War  were 
finally  determined,  the  bulk  of  the  public  debt  of  England 
as  it  stood  prior  to  the  recent  world  war  was  created.  The 
wars  of  William  III  were  the  cause  of  £18  million  of  debt 
and  the  wars  of  Anne  of  £33  million  more.  The  Spanish 
Right  of  Search  War  and  the  War  of  the  Austrian  Succession 
piled  on  another  £31  million.  The  Seven  Years'  War  added 
£57  million,  the  American  War  £116  million,  and  the  Great 
French  Wars  £612  million.  The  total  debt  at  the  end  of  the 
period,  allowing  for  some  reductions  during  the  intervals  of 
peace  lying  between  the  different  wars,  was  £850  million. 

The  table  on  page  81  summarizes  these  data.  It  also 
affords  comparisons  not  only  of  one  period  with  another, 
but  also  with  the  national  wealth.  It  is  interesting  to  note 
how  the  growth  in  population  and  in  wealth  kept  pace  to  a 
measurable  extent  with  the  growth  of  the  debt.  This  was 
especially  the  case  during  the  last  50  years  of  the  period. 
A  table  giving  similar  comparisons  of  the  debt  charge  for 

79 


80  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

the  same  periods  with  the  national  income  may  be  found 
on  page  116. 

Public  Finance  in  the  Reign  of  William  III 

The  reign  of  William  III  was  marked  by  active  warfare 
at  home  and  abroad.  At  home  there  was  the  cruel  war  for 
the  reduction  of  Ireland.  Abroad  there  was  constant  warfare 
with  France,  which  had  espoused  the  cause  of  the  deposed 
King,  James  II,  and  also  was  at  war  with  England's  ally, 
HoUand. 

The  expenditures  during  the  reign  of  James,  which  had 
been  called  "crushing,"  had  averaged  ^^2, 168,000  a  year. 
They  mounted  to  an  average  of  nearly  £5  million  in  William's 
reign.  This  state  of  affairs  constituted  a  serious  menace  to 
the  stability  of  the  new  government,  not  altogether  removed 
by  the  final  victory.  To  cope  with  such  a  difficulty  William 
had  the  advantage  of  the  experience  of  the  Dutch  in  financial 
matters.  In  the  Bank  of  Amsterdam,  established  in  1609, 
the  Dutch  possessed  one  of  the  three  important  banks  of  the 
time.  England  was  rich  and  had  come  to  understand  and 
to  engage  actively  in  company  promotion  and  in  stock  specula- 
tion. Domestic  business  was  active,  much  capital  having 
been  invested  during  the  war  in  the  manufacture  of  goods 
of  a  class  formerly  imported  from  France.  There  had  also 
been  an  active  development  of  mining  ventures,  water  supply 
companies,   munitions  factories  and  other  undertakings. 

As  the  war  progressed,  French  commerce  was  driven  off 
the  seas.  England  was  rapidly  becoming  the  greatest 
commercial  country  in  Europe. 

The  Bank  of  England  Founded 

The  requirements  of  the  State  and  of  business  both  called 
for  better  banking  facilities  than  were  offered  by  the  Gold- 
smiths. The  time  was  ripe  for  the  introduction  of  corporate 
banking.  Therefore,  when  a  plan  was  brought  forward  for 
organizing  a  bank  which  would  make  an  immediate  large 
advance  of  capital  to  the  State  and  which  would  stand  ready 


00      S 
1-1       o 


00     j- 


H 

Q 

-s» 

W 

O 

Ui 

t>i 

« 

Q 

Oh 

^ 

J 

^ 

"« 

< 

< 

a 

^ 

U 

o 

O 

Pi 

« 

H 

:?; 

ffi 

-« 

^ 

w 

0 

2 

w  q 


^         .:4 

'-ir>oor>oo<35!35c^jir)c<>»*' 

— >  oo 

Deb 

Per 

Cent 

Weall 

CO  -^ 

^^^^c^^c.,^ 

C-)  m 

•S        rt 

•OOCOCOCOCDr>Cn005C<5 

c^co 

ii  1-,  -S 

1— <    *^                                   T-H    f— 1                         7-H 

*— < 

►-„   "^  oJ 

>^-H(NrtC>l(M<35C^O  —  ■* 

a>  00 

N^CO  COCOt^OOOOt^C^OM-* 

1/5  1/5 

r-<  T-c  r-l 

-<  ^ 

ni 

^Tfoor-cDujwf-Hirxi) 

t^O 

Debl 
per 
apiti 

'"'                               ^ 

"-+30  eccca30owiMO^r^<J)t^ 

\r>  o 

--<  -1  ^  ^  c^  e<i 

■^  lo 

Na- 
tional 
Wealth. 

ooooooooooo 

oo 

lMiM(NI>00OOomOU5 

U5  O 

^HJCO  <:C«CCl'*l/5'«U5I>0_«N 

-h"c^' 

«       S- 

lang 
rom 
evioi 
iriod 

•^'^■*«<3lfi>Ot^<MC<5<M 

<N  00 

N^  1  r>"rocrr    "  T-."  •<*  t>r  W5  co"  50 

CO*  id" 

'  ^      e^      CO      U5      -H 

CO  "* 

G  a:^ 

'^ 

C^  cc 

•4-> 

®.  ■*.  ^.  ^.  '^.  ^.  ■*  ""^  "l  ^.  ® 

(N  O 

XI 

,_, -h"  !»  in  oo"  Qo"  oj"  ic  eo  r*"  ^f  aT 

^M         r-^  — <  Tt  -I"  C^  O  CC  C^  '*  CO 

-*"o" 

O 

O  lO 

Q 

--<  — ■  IN  IM 

IC  00 

ex  ° 

C<l_  (N  --<_  (N  00_  0_  C<I^  Oi  IC  C<)^  I> 

oo 

O  +J 

irT  uo"  ic  1/5  ic  co"  <D  (D  i>  cd"  oo" 

^"K 

pHi3 

oor^  —  -^OiOiificcifiuocN 

C<1  t^ 

oo05o^cO'*i/2cci>xa) 

o  — 

cDcoi>c^c^t^i>t~»r^r^r^ 

00  00 

-d 

.—1  .-1 

D 

* 

T) 

-  -M 

Nov. 
Sep 

Oct 

d    - 

}—i 

rC                                                                               J3 

^     -t--                                                                              -t-" 

ji 

-t-ios    ::::;;    :o    ; 

-u    ; 

ir>c<\                                ^ 

i« 

' 

III    *           '. 
Wars 

1 

TJ 

i-i 

O 

•c 

Ah 

on 
William 

Anne     . 

Austrian 

ears  War 

nWar 

■ench  Wa 

riod 

eriod 

-M  MH            S-l             iH            ^             <^ 

DO          O        -«        "^          O 

^s:^ 

-M    4^-0 

n  1^  a 

^  -2  ^'^  >S  «■"    &(«'>^    M  ^'^    •=  ^'^    >- 

B 
o 

GO 


13 

(3 

c 

C3 

CJ 

Cfi 

(u  tJ 

4) 

() 

-a 

a 

c 

nt 

oi 
o 

a 

t3 

« 

a 

d 

rt 

fl 

>, 

q 

ri 

^ 

o 

C  T) 

•  rH 

a 

r/) 

01 

S 

60 

V 

n 

HH 

W 

6— (1823) 


82  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

to  finance  the  growing  requirements  of  the  Government,  and 
also  of  the  commercial  classes,  it  found  a  ready  response, 
and  in  1694  the  Bank  of  England  was  organized. 

The  National  Debt  Inaugurated 

Another  idea  which  William  brought  with  him  from  Hol- 
land was  that  of  national  borrowing.  The  new  Government 
hesitated  to  place  upon  the  people  too  heavy  a  burden  of 
taxation.  It  was  also  thought  to  be  a  good  policy  to  have 
the  moneyed  classes  tied  to  the  Government  by  direct 
investment  in  the  public  funds. 

It  is  an  interesting  fact  that  the  methods  of  public  borrowing 
introduced  during  the  reign  of  William  III  comprised  prac- 
tically every  method  since  adopted.  This  indicates  at  once 
the  resourcefulness  of  William's  finance  ministers  and  the 
conservatism  of  the  English  people.  Then,  as  now,  the 
debt  assumed  two  principal  forms — funded  and  unfunded. 
According  to  English  Finance  Accounts,  the  funded  debt  con- 
sists only  of  the  perpetual  debt,  such  as  the  debts  due  to  the 
Bank  of  England  and  the  Bank  of  Ireland  and  the  Consols. 
The  unfunded  debt  is  debt  of  a  temporary  nature  and  debt 
repayable  at  the  end  of  fixed  terms.  As  some  of  the  obliga- 
tions under  this  latter  head  are  not  repayable  for  many  years 
the  division  based  on  established  usage  has  become  somewhat 
illogical. 

We  will  now  consider  the  early  forms  of  unfunded  and 
funded  debt. 


CHAPTER  XV 

EARLY  FORMS  OF  THE  UNFUNDED  DEBT 

(1688-1707) 

The  unfunded  debt  of  this  period  consisted  of  Tallies,  Navy 
bills  and  Exchequer  bills.  In  temporary  advances  by  the 
Bank — as  for  convenience  we  will  hereafter  designate  the  Bank 
of  England — we  have  the  precursor  of  the  "Ways  and  Means 
Advances  "  of  present-day  Treasury  statements. 

Tallies 

Prior  to  the  Revolution  the  form  which  the  obligations 
of  the  Crown  usually  took  was  that  of  loans  upon  "  tallies  " — 
a  form  of  wooden  stick  given  as  a  receipt  for  money  payments. 
The  tally  will  be  found  described  in  the  chapter  on  the 
Exchequer. 

The  Exchequer  would  at  times  find  it  inconvenient  to  meet 
its  payments  in  cash.  It  would  then  give  to  the  creditor 
tallies  or  receipts  issued  in  anticipation  of  revenue.  These 
were  known  as  "  Tallies  of  Assignment,"  because  a  definite 
source  of  revenue  was  set  aside  for  their  payment.  They 
were  always  accompanied  by  an  Exchequer  order  entitling 
the  holder  to  the  payment  of  the  amount  at  a  set  date  in 
the  future. 

These  Exchequer  orders  were  issued  in  negotiable  form, 
being  transferable  by  endorsement.  They  sometimes  bore 
interest. 

Again,  tallies  with  assignable  orders  of  repayment  were 
given  in  acknowledgment  of  money  loans.  These  tallies  were 
called  "Tallies  of  Loan."  The  Exchequer  order  of  repayment 
was  the  really  valuable  document.  It  was  written  on  parch- 
ment and  signed  by  the  high  Exchequer  and  Treasury  officials. 

These  orders  and  the  tallies  accompanying  them  came  in 
time  to  be  known  indifferently  as  "tallies,"  and  the  operation 

83 


84  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

was  spoken  of  as  borrowing  on  tallies.  The  following  is  a 
copy  of  such  a  document  of  the  time  of  Charles  II. 

EXCHEQUER  ORDER. 

Reign  of  Charles  II. 

Order  is  taken  by  us,  this.  .  .  .  day  of by  virtue  of  an 

Act  intituled,  "  An  Act  for  granting  a  Supply  to  His  Majesty  of  Two 
hundred  and  six  thousand,  foure  hundred  sixty-two  pounds,  seaventeene 
shilUngs  and  three  pence,  for  paying  off  and  disbanding  the  Forces 
raised  since  the  Nine  and  twentyeth  of  September,  One  thousand  six 
hundred  seaventy  and  seaven,"  that  you  deliver  and  pay  of  such  of 
His  Majestye's  treasure  as  remains  in  your  charge  of  the  summe  of 
Two  hundred  and  six  thousand  fower  hundred  sixty-two  pounds, 
seaventeene  sliillings,  and  three  pence,  arising  by  virtue  of  the  said  Act 

unto or  his  assignes,  the  summe  of in  repayment  of 

soe  much  money  lent  by  him  unto  hi?  Majestic  upon  the  credit  of  the 
said  summe  of  Two  hundred  six  thousand  fower  hundred  sixtie-two 
pounds,   seaventeene   shillings,   and  three  pence,   and   paid  into  the 

receipt  of  his  majestie's  Exchequer,  the  said day  of 

as  by  a  tally  leavied  at  the  receipt  of  the  Exchequer,  bearing  date  the 
same  day,  appears,  together  with  the  interest  thereof,  at  the  rate  of 
eight  pounds  per  centum  per  annum,  at  the  end  of  every  three  months, 
until  the  repayment  of  the  principall  ;  and  these,  together  with  his 
or  her  acquittance,  or  the  acquittance  of  his  or  her  assignee  or  assignees, 
shall  be  your  discharge  herein. 

The  first  loans  of  William  III  were  raised  in  the  usual  way 
by  tallies  of  loan  charged  on  and  in  anticipation  of  various 
duties.  The  amounts  required  were  so  large  that  they 
accumulated  more  rapidly  than  the  revenues  allocated  to 
them  could  be  collected.  Then  the  Treasury  frequently  was 
not  in  funds  with  which  to  meet  a  given  series  of  tallies 
because  the  collections  were  smaller  than  the  charges.  Thus 
the  tallies  were  discredited  and  fell  to  a  heavy  discount. 
At  the  close  of  the  war  in  1696  the  total  deficiency  in  the 
funds  upon  which  the  tallies  outstanding  were  charged  was 
£5,160,000.  To  remedy  this  defect  in  the  system  Parliament 
swept  all  of  the  receipts  into  one  fund,  making  all  outstanding 
tallies  a  first  general  mortgage  thereon. 

The  debt  upon  tallies  of  loan  was  a  very  dangerous  form 
of  unfunded  debt.  As  these  loans  were  usually  made  only 
for  short  periods,  the  Treasury  was  under  the  necessity  of 
making  frequent  renewals.  These  renewals  were  apt  to  come 
at  inconvenient  times. 


EARLY  FORMS  OF  THE  UNFUNDED  DEBT        85 

Navy  and  Army  Supply  Bills 

The  records  show,  especially  in  the  case  of  tallies  of  antici- 
pation, that  the  Army  and  Navy  paymasters  frequently  had 
to  submit  to  a  heavy  discount.  As  high  a  loss  as  25  per  cent. 
is  known  to  have  been  suffered  during  the  financial  distress  of 
1687.  In  the  following  year  the  Treasury  was  authorized  by 
Parliament  to  issue  these  tallies  at  10  per  cent,  discount  to 
those  who  would  receive  them  in  payment  for  naval  Sf  rvices. 
In  fact  it  was  especially  in  connection  with  naval  services  that 
such  depreciation  chiefly  occurred. 

The  navy  and  army  supply  bills,  as  these  obligations  came 
to  be  known  later  on,  were  put  on  a  sound  basis  in  1784 
during  the  Treasury  administration  of  the  younger  Pitt, 

The  Exchequer  Bill 

The  introduction  of  the  Exchequer  bill  in  1696  was  a  first 
step  toward  remedying  this  abuse,  although  it  was  not  until 
1751  that  they  entirely  supplanted  the  tallies.  They  were 
issued  in  the  first  instance  to  supply  a  temporary  need  for 
a  circulating  medium  while  the  coinage  was  in  process  of 
revision.  Bank  of  England  notes  were  not  issued  at  that 
time  in  smaller  denominations  than  twenty  pounds.  The 
Exchequer  bills  then  issued  amounted  to  only  £159,169,  but 
in  the  next  year  £1,500,000  were  issued  and  in  the  following 
year  £1,200,000  more.  They  were  issued  in  even  denomina- 
tions of  five  and  ten  pounds  and  to  such  public  creditors  as 
chose  to  receive  them.  There  was  no  compulsion.  They 
were  negotiable,  passing  by  endorsement.  They  bore  interest. 
They  were  receivable  by  the  Government  in  payment  for  all 
taxes,  except  the  land  tax,  and  when  received  could  be 
reissued.  Interest  lapsed  during  the  time  they  were  in  the 
Treasury.  When  the  bills  were  covered  with  endorsements 
they  were  held  in  the  Treasury  and  other  bills  issued  in  their 
stead. 

In  1707  an  issue  of  Exchequer  bills  was  authorized  receiv- 
able for  taxes,  or  payable  at  the  Exchequer  for  any  obligation 


86  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

due  by  the  Government,  and  exchangeable  for  ready  money 
on  demand  at  the  Bank  of  England.  An  allowance  of  4 J  per 
cent,  per  annum  was  made  to  the  Bank  for  circulating  the 
bills.  These  bills  bore  no  interest  when  issued  from  the 
Exchequer,  the  amount  of  interest  to  be  paid  thereon  being 
left  to  the  discretion  of  the  Bank.  The  Bank  was  then  in  a 
position  to  guide  the  Exchequer  as  to  the  amount  of  bills 
which  could  be  safely  placed  in  circulation.  The  amount 
outstanding  from  time  to  time  varied  with  the  exigencies  of 
the  Exchequer.  The  use  of  the  bills  as  an  active  circulat- 
ing medium  was  regulated  by  raising  or  lowering  the 
denominations  in  which  they  were  issued. 
The  Exchequer  bills  first  issued  were  worded  as  follows  : 

EXCHEQUER  BILL. 
Reign  of  William  III. 
No.  188.  Exchequer, 

26th  April,  1697. 
By  virtue  of  an  Act  of  Parliament  passed  in  the  viii  year  of  his 
Maties  Reign,  This  Bill  entitles  the  bearer  to  Five  Pounds,  to  pass  in 
all  payments  to  Receiv"  or  Collectors  of  any  Ayds  Taxes  or  Supplys 
for  the  service  of  the  War  for  the  year  1697  (except  ye  III  ShiUing 
Ayd),  to  be  reed  and  satisfied  by  y*  said  Receive  or  Collect"  under 
ye  Penalties  in  ye  Act  contained. 

R.  Howard.  A  farthing  a  day  (LS.) 

interest. 

When  the  issues  of  Exchequer  bills  became  excessive  they 
were  funded  into  other  forms  of  debt.  Thus  they  afforded 
a  flexible  credit  instrument  which  could  be  increased  or 
decreased  as  required  by  the  necessities  of  the  Government. 


CHAPTER  XVI 

EARLY  FORMS  OF  THE  FUNDED  DEBT 

(1688-1727) 

The  early  forms  of  funded  debt  were  annuities  and  the 
perpetual  loans  from  the  Bank  and  the  East  India  Company 
and  later  from  the  South  Sea  Company  given  in  exchange 
for  their  charter  privileges. 

Annuities 

The  annuity  loans  were  made  on  the  same  theory  as  that 
upon  which  annuities  are  sold  to-day  by  insurance  companies. 

The  seller  of  an  annuity  agrees,  in  consideration  of  the 
receipt  of  a  given  sum  of  money,  to  make  the  purchaser 
annually  or  otherwise,  during  his  lifetime,  or  for  a  specified 
period,  a  definite  payment.  This  payment  is  larger  than  the 
interest  would  be  upon  the  principal  sum  because  upon  the 
death  of  the  purchaser,  or  upon  the  expiration  of  the  annuity 
period  the  sum  which  he  originally  paid,  or  what  may  remain 
of  it  becomes  the  absolute  property  of  the  seller.  That  is, 
in  the  case  of  a  pure  life  annuity,  the  seller  and  the  purchaser 
speculate  upon  the  probable  life  of  the  purchaser,  the  latter 
to  increase  his  income,  the  former  with  a  view  to  profit. 
Present-day  tables  based  upon  a  study  by  insurance  actuaries 
of  the  expectancy  of  life  are  remarkably  accurate  in  indicating 
the  average  expectancy  of  life  at  a  given  age.  The  whole 
principle  of  insurance  is  based  on  this  theory  of  averages. 

The  tontine  policy  was  invented  by  an  Italian  of  the  name 
of  Tonti.  He  devised  a  plan  by  which  a  group  of  individuals 
would  agree  with  the  seller  of  an  annuity  and  with  each  other 
that,  as  members  of  the  group  died,  the  survivors  should  have 
divided  among  them  the  amounts  to  which  the  decedents 
would  have  been  entitled  until  eventually  the  entire  annuity, 

87 


88  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

or  an  agreed  proportion  thereof,  would  go  to  the  final 
survivor. 

The  loan  of  1692  for  £1  million  was  offered  on  this  basis, 
the  benefit  of  survivorship  to  last  until  the  group  was  reduced 
to  seven.  The  idea  was  new  in  England  and  not  understood, 
so  the  loan  was  a  failure,  only  ;fl08,000  being  raised.  At 
subsequent  periods  several  tontine  annuity  loans  were 
placed. 

In  1695  long  annuities  having  90  years  certain  duration 
were  introduced. 

The  annuity  principle  for  funded  loans  was  the  one  chiefly 
used  during  the  eighteenth  century.  It  was  often  used  in 
combination  with  other  schemes.  One  of  these  which  came 
to  be  increasingly  in  vogue  until  the  close  of  the  American 
War  in  1783  was  the  lottery  loan  which  will  be  found  described 
in  Chapter  XVII. 

The  "  Fund  of  Credit  "  Idea 

There  was  a  theory  prevalent  in  the  latter  part  of  the 
seventeenth  century  and  the  early  part  of  the  eighteenth 
century  known  to  economists  as  the  "  fund  of  credit  "  idea. 
It  was  in  pursuance  of  this  idea  that  the  Bank  of  England 
was  organized.  The  entire  original  capital  of  the  Bank  as 
well  as  part  of  the  deposits  were  loaned  to  the  nation.  This 
left  the  Bank  as  a  basis  for  conducting  its  business  a  "  fund 
of  credit  "  founded  upon  its  loan  to  the  Government.  Similar 
was  the  policy  of  Parliament  in  forcing  the  East  India  Com- 
pany to  pass  on  to  the  Government  in  exchange  for  its 
obligations  the  proceeds  of  its  sales  of  stock.  A  bank  known 
as  the  Million  Bank  was  organized  in  1695  on  the  same  basis 
and  for  a  while  conducted  a  moderately  successful  business. 
Pushed  to  its  logical  conclusion,  such  an  idea  could  be 
developed  indefinitely.  Its  prevalence  was  not  confined  to 
England.  The  idea  was  at  the  basis  of  the  organization 
of  the  South  Sea  Company  which  was  chartered  in  1711, 
and  of  John  Law's  Mississippi  Company  which  had  such  a 
meteoric  career  a  few  years  later  in  France. 


EARLY  FORMS  OF  THE  FUNDED  DEBT         89 

The  East  India  Company 

The  original  East  India  Company  was  chartered  by  Queen 
EUzabeth  in  the  year  1600.  To  it  was  given  the  exclusive 
privilege  of  trade  for  fifteen  years.  This  period  was  subse- 
quently extended  from  time  to  time,  to  Asia,  Africa,  and  to 
America  and  intervening  islands  from  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope 
to  the  Straits  of  Magellan. 

The  company  opened  up  trade  with  India  and  became  a 
rich  and  powerful  corporation.  The  success  of  the  company 
led  to  efforts  at  competition  and  finally  to  the  organization 
in  1698,  under  parliamentary  act,  of  a  dangerous  rival.  The 
consideration  for  the  charter  of  the  new  company  was  that 
it  should  make  a  loan  to  the  State  of  £2  million.  When 
the  stock  was  offered,  the  old  company  subscribed  £315,000 
and  became  the  dominant  factor  in  the  new  body.  Finally, 
in  1702  in  the  reign  of  Queen  Anne,  the  companies  were 
merged  and  given  exclusive  privileges  in  consideration  of  a 
further  loan  of  £1,200,000. 

The  story  of  the  East  India  Company  is  one  of  the 
romances  of  commerce.  It  was  through  its  efforts  that  the 
great  Empire  of  India  was  won  for  Great  Britain.  Its 
famous  "  East  Indiamen  "  held  unquestioned  pre-eminence 
among  the  merchant  vessels  of  the  world  down  to  the  middle 
of  the  nineteenth  century.  Some  of  the  most  stirring  chapters 
in  England's  commercial  history  are  written  around  the 
voyages  of  these  ships  and  the  stories  of  Clive  and  Hastings 
will  ever  be  memorable  in  England's  military  history. 

India  has  been  the  great  imperial  training  school  for  a 
long  line  of  illustrious  British  soldiers  and  administrators. 
The  government  was  taken  over  by  the  Crown  in  1858,  after 
the  mutiny. 

The  South  Sea  Company 

The  most  spectacular  operation  based  upon  the  fund  of 
credit  idea  was  that  with  the  South  Sea  Company.  This 
company  was  at  its  inception  to  all  intents  a  government 


90  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

undertaking,  although  incorporated  (in  September,  1711)  as 
a  private  company.     It  received  a  charter  giving  it  exclusive 
trading  rights  to  the  east  coast  of  South  America  with  certain 
limited  exceptions  and  a  monopoly  of  trading  in  the  Pacific 
Ocean,  including    the    entire    American    Pacific   Coast.     In 
consideration  of  these  trading  rights,  which  were  expected 
to  have  great  value,  the  company  was  to  offer  to  exchange 
its  stock  for  the  outstanding  unfunded  government   debt 
and  in  addition  was  to  pay  the  Government  £500,000.     The 
Government  was  to  pay  the  company  interest  at  the  rate 
of  6  per  cent,  per  annum  upon  all  stock  which  it  should 
thus  acquire  and  in  addition  £8,000  a  year  for  management. 
This  offer  was  accepted,  up  to  the  close   of    1711,  by  the 
holders  of  upwards  of  £9  million  of  government  obligations. 
Fmther    exchanges   and   adjustments,    in    1714,    made   the 
capital  and  the  debt  balance  at  an  even  £10  million.     A 
further  small  operation  took  place  in   1719  when  the  sum 
of  £1,746,844  was  converted.     At  this  time  those  in  control 
of  the  company  and  their  associates  in  the   Government 
determined  upon  an  operation  of  no  less  importance  than 
that  of  the  conversion  of  the  entire  balance  of  the  debt  into 
the  company's  stock.     If  this  scheme  could  have  been  car- 
ried out  the  company  would  have  had  a  capital  of  around 
£50   million   and   would  have  practically   monopolized  the 
banking  and  trading  business  of  the  kingdom.     However, 
the  Bank  and  the  East  India  Company  would  not  come  into 
the  arrangement.     It  was  then  decided  to  go  ahead  without 
them.     By  wholesale  bribery  of  the  members  of  Parliament 
and  of  government  officials,  and  by  collusion  with  no  less  a 
person  than  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  the  necessary 
legislation  was  obtained  and  the  plan  successfully  launched. 
This  was  not  accomplished  without  active  competition  from 
the  Bank.     The  competitive  bidding  of  the  Bank  led  the 
company  finally  to  offer  the  Government   very  attractive 
terms.     Provided  all  of  the  holders  of  government  obliga- 
tions, except  the  Bank  and  the  East  India  Company,  converted 
their  holdings  the  company  was  to  pay  the  Government 


EARLY  FORMS  OF  THE  FUNDED  DEBT         91 

£7,567,500  and  was  to  surrender  its  trading  rights,  but  with 
a  tacit  understanding  with  Aislabie,  the  Chancellor  of  the 
Exchequer,  that  they  would  be  restored  later  on.  The 
Government  in  turn  was  to  pay  interest  at  5  per  cent,  per 
annum  upon  its  obligations  acquired  by  the  company.  It 
was  agreed  that  after  1727  the  interest  rate  should  be  reduced 
to  4  per  cent.  The  advantage  to  the  nation  lay  in  this 
saving  of  1  per  cent,  in  interest  and  in  the  receipt  of  the 
cash  payment  of  £1\  million.  Manifestly,  even  if  trading 
rights  were  restored,  which  was  part  of  the  programme,  there 
was  no  legitimate  basis  for  such  a  payment  by  the  company. 

The  Outcome  of  South  Sea  Scheme 

The  profit  to  the  promoters  was  to  come  from  stock  market 
operations  on  a  huge  scale  and  they  little  cared  what  hap- 
pened afterward  to  their  new  stockholders,  the  present  holders 
of  government  debt.  By  spreading  tales  of  the  great  profits 
to  be  derived  from  their  trading  rights — for  they  took  good 
care  not  to  let  it  be  known  that  these  had  been  surrendered 
— and  by  the  rankest  kind  of  stock  market  manipulation 
they  forced  the  quotations  of  their  stock  up  to  200,  then  to 
300,  then  to  800  and  finally  to  1,050.  As  the  stock  advanced 
they  offered  the  holders  of  government  debt  the  privilege 
of  exchanges  at  three  to  one,  then  at  four  to  one.  As  their 
terms  with  the  Government  were  for  even  exchanges  they 
thus  accumulated  a  large  amount  of  treasury  stock,  some  of 
which  they  were  able  to  sell  at  the  advanced  prices  and  thus 
to  accumulate  a  temporary  dividend  fund  and  one  for  use  in 
manipulating  the  market.  If  the  plan  could  have  been 
carried  out  in  its  entirety  the  profits  realized  upon  the  private 
holdings  of  the  "  insiders  "  would  have  been  immense.  The 
magnitude  of  the  operation  and  the  rapidity  of  the  advance 
proved  to  be  their  undoing.  Other  promoters  came  into  the 
market  with  their  schemes  and  a  wild  orgy  of  speculation 
took  place.  As  usually  happens  in  such  a  market,  the  col- 
lapse, when  it  came,  was  sudden  and  severe.  The  exchange 
of  public  securities  for  the  company's  stock  had  been  achieved, 


95^  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

but  the  speculators  were  most  of  them  ruined  and  the  public 
robbed.  Strange  as  it  may  seem,  the  company  remained 
solvent.  Its  new  stockholders,  most  of  them  the  former 
holders  of  government  obligations,  held  the  stock  at  varying 
prices.  The  Government  had  to  surrender  its  right  to  the 
£1\  million,  and  to  make  the  company  a  temporary  loan 
of  a  million  pounds  in  the  form  of  Exchequer  bills.  It  carried 
out  its  contract  to  pay  the  5  per  cent,  per  annum  until  1727, 
and  then  4  per  cent.,  which  yielded  a  corresponding  return 
upon  the  company's  stock.  The  conspirators  were  severely 
punished  by  loss  of  office,  imprisonment  and  loss  of  property. 
The  worst  sufferers  were  those  among  the  public  who  were 
tempted  to  speculate  in  this  and  the  various  schemes  which 
were  promoted  during  the  period  of  the  craze.  For  a  long 
time  afterward  stock  speculation  was  much  in  disfavour  and 
"  Change  Alley  "  neglected. 

The  subsequent  history  of  the  company  can  be  quickly 
told.  It  existed  until  1854  purely  as  an  investment  cor- 
poration holding  government  debt,  receiving  the  interest 
thereon  and  disbursing  it  to  its  stockholders.  Finally,  in 
1854,  the  last  of  the  debt  was  paid  and  the  company  liquidated. 


CHAPTER  XVII 

STATE    LOTTERIES   AND    LOTTERY    LOANS 

(1694-1826) 

The  first  lottery  loan  was  raised  in  1694.  The  lottery 
principle  had  long  been  known  and  used  on  the  Continent 
and  was  not  entirely  new  to  England. 

The  First  English  Lotteries 

The  first  English  lottery  of  which  there  is  any  record  was 
one  projected  in  the  reign  of  Elizabeth  and  issued  under  her 
patronage  in  the  year  1569.  The  bill  announcing  it  states 
that  "  the  same  Lotterie  is  erected  by  her  majestie's  orders  to 
the  intent  that  such  commoditie  as  may  chaunce  to  arise 
thereof,  after  the  charges  borne,  may  be  converted  towardes 
the  reparation  of  the  havens  and  Strength  of  the  Realme,  and 
towards  such  other  publique  good  workes,"  We  have  no 
record  as  to  the  amount  which  it  yielded. 

A  loan  by  lottery  was  raised  in  the  time  of  James  I,  the 
proceeds  being  used  to  defray  the  expenses  attending  the 
establishment  of  the  colonies  in  America.  - 

The  first  lottery  loan  of  King  William  III  was  for  £1  million. 
It  was  offered  in  shares  of  £10.  Annuities  of  £14  per  cent, 
for  16  years  were  variously  apportioned,  £14  per  cent,  on 
every  share  and  a  larger  proportion  for  the  holders  of  2,500 
fortunate  tickets.  The  principal  prize  was  £1,000.  The 
annuity  of  £140,000  was  made  a  charge  upon  the  salt  duties. 
The  operation  was  called  the  Million  Lottery  and  the  annuities 
the  Salt  Lottery  Annuities. 

There  were  seven  lottery  loans  from  1711  to  1714  in 
the  reign  of  Queen  Anne  which  yielded  to  the  Government 
£9  minion,  but  the  bonuses  paid  to  the  holders  of  fortunate 
lottery  tickets  amounted  to  £2,734,000. 

93 


94  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

The  use  of  State  lotteries  in  connection  with  the  Spanish- 
Austrian  War  financing,  1743-1748,  gave  a  guise  of  respecta- 
bihty  to  this  method  of  raising  money.  It  is  not  surprising, 
therefore,  to  find  that  bridges  were  built  over  the  Thames, 
and  the  British  Museum  founded  with  funds  derived  from 
lotteries. 

Lottery  Loans  in  the  American  War 

It  was  in  connection  with  the  financing  of  the  American 
War  (1775-1783)  that  the  lottery  loan  had  its  greatest  vogue. 

The  loans  offered  were  all  on  the  lottery  basis.  They  were 
sold  at  a  progressively  heavy  discount.     In  1776  for  £2  million 

the  Treasury  offered  for  every  £100  subscribed — 

i    s.  d. 
3  per  cent,  stock        .  .  .  .  .  .     77  10     - 

And  three  lottery  tickets  (in  all  60,000)  valued  at 
;^10  each  ;  the  prizes  being  funded,  the  holders 
of  the  fortunate  lottery  tickets  received  at  par 
3  per  cent,  stock    .  .  .  .  .  .     30     -     - 

Or  in  all  for  ;^100  cash        ....  ;^107   10     - 


The  next  loan  was  in  4  per  cent,  stock  at  par  with  a  10s. 
short  annuity  ;  the  two  following  were  in  3  per  cent,  stock 
at  par  with  more  liberal  annuities.  Then  came  another  at 
4  per  cent,  at  par  with  an  annuity.  Finally  with  the  growing 
necessities  of  the  Government  and  increasing  depreciation 
of  government  stock  it  was  necessary  in  1781  to  offer,  for 
£12  million  in  cash,  £18  million  3  per  cents  and  £3  million  fours. 
Again,  in  1782,  for  £13|  million  cash,  the  Treasury  gave  the 
same  amount  in  threes,  50  per  cent,  additional  in  fours  and 
a  liberal  annuity.  The  loans  of  1783  and  1784  were  placed 
on  substantially  the  same  basis,  although  it  was  found 
necessary  in  1783  to  give  only  25  per  cent,  in  fours,  but  in 
1784  it  was  necessary  to  give  50  per  cent,  again,  but  a  smaller 
annuity  was  given. 

Every  one  of  these  loans  carried  the  privilege  of  pur- 
chasing, at  £10  each,  a  certain  percentage  of  lottery  tickets. 
For  instance,  in  connection  with  the  £6  million  loan  of  1778 


STATE   LOTTERIES   AND   LOTTERY   LOANS  95 

there  were  48,000  lottery  tickets.  Each  subscriber  of  £1,000 
received  an  equivalent  amount  of  3  per  cent,  stock  and  an 
annuity  for  30  years  of  £2  10s.  on  each  £100,  practically 
5 J  per  cent,  for  30  years,  with  the  privilege  of  purchasing 
eight  lottery  tickets  for  an  additional  payment  of  £80.  In 
the  case  of  the  loan  of  1782  a  subscriber  of  £1,000  received 
£1,000  in  3  per  cent,  stock,  £500  in  4  per  cent,  stock  and 
a  long  annuity  of  17s.  6d.  on  each  £100.  He  also  might 
subscribe  for  three  lottery  tickets. 

The  prizes,  which  amounted  to  the  total  sum  paid  for  the 
tickets,  were  not  funded  as  they  had  been  at  other  times,  but 
were  paid  in  cash  to  the  holders  of  the  fortunate  tickets  in  the 
Spring  of  the  following  year.  It  would  thus  appear  that  the 
Government  made  no  direct  gain  from  the  lottery  itself, 
acting  merely,  as  it  were,  as  an  agent  or  stake  holder,  being 
benefited  by  the  incentive  given  to  the  public  to  take  the 
loan. 

How  the  Loans  Were  Placed 

An  intelligent  contemporary  writer  has  given  us  a  record 
as  to  how  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  was  accustomed 
to  place  loans  during  this  period.  He  tells  us  that  it  was 
usual  for  the  minister  to  confer  in  private  with  a  few  moneyed 
men  as  to  the  terms  of  the  loan  and  thus  to  determine  a  basis 
which  would  be  acceptable  to  the  market. 

We  are  not  advised  whether  at  this  time  the  bankers 
"  underwrote  "  the  sale  of  the  loan,  but  we  knov/  that  at  a 
later  date  it  became  customary  for  them  to  purchase  the  loan 
in  bulk  and  then  to  distribute  it  to  their  patrons  at  a  moderate 
advance.  When  a  new  loan  was  contracted  prior  to  the 
payment  of  the  last  instalment  of  a  preceding  loan,  it  was 
usual  to  give  the  preference  to  the  contractors  for  the  preceding 
loan. 

As  it  was  illegal  for  a  private  individual  to  pay  or  receive 
over  5  per  cent,  interest  for  money,  it  was  apparently  deemed 
improper  for  the  State  to  offer  a  higher  rate.  Therefore  in 
order  to  draw  capital  to  the  Exchequer  it  was  deemed  necessary 


96  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

to  make  the  offering  attractive  in  other  ways  than  by  directly 
giving  a  higher  rate  of  interest.  The  Treasury  oflficials  seem 
to  have  thought  chiefly  about  the  addition  which  the  debt 
charge  would  make  to  the  budget.  They  were  not  much 
concerned  about  the  nominal  par  value  of  the  debt.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  bankers  naturally  desired  terms  which  would 
make  the  loan  attractive  to  the  public  and  thus  readily 
negotiable.  At  the  same  time  they  very  naturally  wanted 
such  terms  as  would  afford  opportunities  for  a  handsome 
profit  on  their  part,  if  not  at  the  time,  at  any  rate  in  the  subse- 
quent dealings  in  the  market.  Hence  it  became  customary 
during  Lord  North's  incumbency  of  the  Exchequer,  as  already 
stated,  for  every  £1,000  in  money  to  give  3  per  cent,  and 
4  per  cent,  stock,  either  or  both,  equivalent  in  market  value 
to  the  money  to  be  advanced,  with  an  annuity  in  addition, 
in  some  cases,  and,  in  every  instance,  with  the  privilege  of 
purchasing  a  certain  percentage  of  lottery  tickets.  The 
subscription  was  still  further  "  sweetened  "  by  making  the 
money  payable  in  instalments  over  a  period  of  months, 
the  purchaser  being  entitled  to  all  interest  accrued  from  the 
date  of  the  loan.  This  last  privilege  amounted  in  some 
cases  to  as  much  as  two-fifths  of  a  year's  interest. 

For  the  payment  against  each  class  of  obligation  issued 
receipts  were  given.  These  receipts  were  called  "  scrip." 
When  handled  together  they  were  spoken  of  as  the  "omnium." 
Transactions  during  the  period  before  the  loan  was  paid  up 
in  full  might  be  either  in  the  several  classes  of  "  scrip  "  or 
in  the  "  omnium."  The  subscriber  had  the  privilege  of 
paying  in  full,  which  privilege  if  exercised  entitled  him  to  a 
cash    discount. 

The  way  in  which  the  dealers  and  investors  in  government 
loans  estimated  the  market  value  of  the  "  omnium  "  was 
this  :  The  lottery  tickets  always  had  an  independent  market. 
Experience  showed  that  an  immediate  sale  could  be  made  of 
these  tickets  at  a  profit  of  from  2s.  to  3s.  each,  depending 
upon  the  total  amount  of  tickets  in  the  lottery.  The  value  of 
the  3  per  cent,  or  4  per  cent,  stock  received  was  determined  by 


STATE   LOTTERIES  AND  LOTTERY  LOANS  97 

current  Stock  Exchange  quotations.  For  example,  in  1782, 
when  the  Exchequer  offered  ^^20,250,000  par  value  for 
£13,500,000  in  money  the  account  worked  out  something  as 
follows — 

For  £100  the  subscriber  received 

i  s.  d. 
1st      ;^100   3%   stock   having   a   market   value 

of,  say        .  .  .  .  .  .  60     -     - 

2nd    ;^50  4%  stock  having  a  market  value  of, 

say  .  .  .  .  .  .  40     -     - 

3rd      A    long    annuity    for     17s.     6d.,     whose 

capitalized  value  would  be  about  .  17     13 

4th     Three-tenths  of  a  lottery  ticket  by  which 

he  would  have  a  profit  of,  say       .  .  11- 

5th     Discount,  due  to  the  fact  that  the  stock 

when  issued  carried  about  two-fifths  of 

a  year's  accrued  interest  for  which  the 

subscriber  was  not  required  to  pay       .  2     -     - 


Total ;^120     2     3 


It  does  not  necessarily  follow  that  these  prices  were  realized 
by  the  lenders.  For  instance,  the  price  of  3  per  cent,  stock 
fluctuated  in  1782  between  61  and  53f.  However,  the 
terms  of  the  loans  at  this  period  were  liberal  and  the 
opportunities  for  profit  were  good. 

The  different  classes  of  scrip  were  actively  dealt  in  in 
'Change  Alley,  as  a  large  speculative  account  could  be  carried 
with  a  very  small  amount  of  cash  capital.  The  subscription 
receipts  paid  in  full  were  called  in  the  Alley  "  heavy  horse," 
while  the  part -paid  certificates  were  known  as  "  light  horse." 
The  "  light  horse  "  was  the  popular  variety  for  speculative 
purposes  and  therefore  commanded  a  relatively  better  price. 
This  was  because  it  took  much  less  capital  to  carry  a  given 
par  amount,  while  the  percentage  of  profit,  if  a  profit  were 
realized,  would  be  larger. 

The  State  Lotteries,  1784- 1826 

We  may  now  conveniently  give  the  further  history  of  the 
State  lotteries. 

7— (1823) 


98  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

After  1784,  the  practice  was  discontinued  of  attaching 
lottery  schemes  to  loan  flotations,  but  until  1823,  a  certain 
percentage  of  the  annual  requirements  of  the  Exchequer  was 
regularly  provided  from  the  proceeds  of  the  sale  of  lottery 
tickets. 

There  were  no  lotteries  in  1824  and  1825  ;  and  in  1826  the 
last  State  lottery  was  drawn,  Ashton,  in  his  "  History  of 
English  Lotteries,"  teUs  us  that  the  method  pursued  by  the 
Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  in  placing  the  lottery  tickets  was 
to  invite  a  few  of  the  leading  stockbrokers  to  a  conference,  in 
which  he  would  state  his  views.  He  would  tell  them  that  he 
intended  to  issue  a  lottery  for,  say,  £500,000  in  ;flO  tickets — 
all  to  be  distributed  as  prizes.  He  would  then  ask  at  what 
price  they  would  tender  for  them.  A  competition  would 
then  ensue  and  finally  an  offer  might  be  accepted  of,  say,  £5 
premium  a  share,  which  would  give  the  Government  a  clear 
profit,  without  risk,  of  £250,000.  Of  course,  those  who 
got  the  concessions  put  up  the  price  of  tickets,  but  as  single 
shares  were  seldom  bought — most  people  taking  a  fourth, 
an  eighth,  or  a  sixteenth  of  a  ticket — ^the  rise  was  not  much 
felt  by  the  public. 

Although  private  lotteries  were  illegal,  nevertheless  they 
seem  to  have  flourished.  The  example  set  by  the  State  was 
followed  by  people  in  all  walks  in  life.  There  were  lottery 
tailors,  lottery  staymakers,  lottery  glovers,  lottery  barbers, 
"  where  a  man  being  shaved,  and  paying  threepence,  may 
stand  a  chance  of  getting  £10."  There  were  even  lottery 
shoeblacks.  There  were  frequent  cases  of  suicide  traced 
to  the  lotteries.  These  were  due  to  the  losing  of  employers' 
money  and  trust  funds  by  those  who  were  tempted  to  gamble 
in  this  way  and  to  disappointed  hopes  of  gain  which  perhaps 
meant  the  loss  of  one's  entire  patrimony.  There  were  many 
fraudulent  practices  connected  with  dealings  in  the  lottery 
tickets. 

The  prizes  varied,  ranging  in  some  instances  from  as  high 
as  £30,000  down  to  £500.  There  were  regular,  reputable 
brokers  who  made  a  business  of  deahng  in  lottery  tickets 


STATE  LOTTERIES  AND   LOTTERY  LOANS  99 

or  shares  in  tickets.  We  are  told  that  no  small  part  of  the 
business  of  the  stockbroker  consisted  of  dealings  in  lottery 
tickets.  There  were  also  many  disreputable  persons  who 
devised  all  sorts  of  schemes  to  make  money  in  connection  with 
the  lotteries.  One  scheme  which  flourished  for  some  time 
was,  for  a  consideration,  to  insure  the  receipt  of  prizes.  This 
was  in  reality  pure  betting.  In  return  for,  say,  a  shilling,  a 
pound  would  be  promised  if  a  certain  specified  number  turned 
up.  Of  course  these  insurances  were  illegal,  but  they  were  so 
profitable  to  the  office-keepers,  that  no  penalties  could  keep 
them  down.  Any  sum  might  be  insured  from  one  to  twenty 
guineas.  The  sum  charged  for  an  insurance  at  the  commence- 
ment of  a  lottery  drawing  gradually  increased  as  the  drawing 
proceeded,  depending  on  whether  the  large  prizes  came  out 
early  or  late.  The  class  preyed  upon  were  principally 
domestic  servants.  In  1800  it  was  computed  that  on  an 
average  each  servant  in  the  metropolis  spent  annually,  as 
much  as  25  shillings  in  this  reprehensible  practice  of  lottery 
insurance.  This  was  when  the  drawing  of  the  lottery  was 
extended  over  days  or  even  weeks. 

As  time  went  on  and  the  evils  of  lottery  became  more 
and  more  apparent,  there  was  a  growing  feehng  that  it 
should  be  abohshed — still,  it  was  not  until  1826  that  en- 
lightened pubhc  opinion   finally  forced  its  discontinuance. 

Those  who  favoured  the  lottery  claimed  that  properly 
conducted  it  was  a  voluntary  tax,  contributed  to  only  by 
those  who  could  afford  it,  and  collected  without  trouble  or 
expense. 

They  claimed  that  most  of  the  evils  connected  with  the 
lottery  had  been  due  to  the  early  practice  of  protracted 
drawings.  In  1809  this  abuse  was  done  away  with  and  the 
lottery  was  decided  in  one  day.  Ashton  tells  us  that  extra- 
ordinary efforts  had  to  be  made  to  dispose  of  the  tickets  for 
the  last  lottery.  The  public  had  become  disgusted  with  this 
method  of  Government  financing  and  were  glad  to  see  it 
discontinued. 

The  State  lotteries  yielded  a  gross  income  of  some  £45 


100  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

million,  but  the  expenses  of  management  and  prizes  absorbed 
over  £33  million.  Thus  the  net  income  from  this  source  was 
about  £12  miUion  or  about  ;£218,000  a  year  for  the  55  times 
between  1755  and  1826  when  this  method  of  raising  revenue 
was   used. 


CHAPTER  XVIII 

THE   SINKING   FUNDS 

We  may  now  profitably  consider  the  early  sinking  fund 
operations.  There  were  two  of  these,  known  respectively 
as  Walpole's  sinking  fund  and  Pitt's  sinking  fund. 

Walpole's  Sinking  Fund 

When  Robert  Walpole  became  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer 
in  October,  1715,  the  pubhc  debt,  including  the  capitahzed 
value  of  the  annuities,  amounted  to  around  £50  miUion 
and  the  annual  charge  to  £3,164,000. 

The  people  were  genuinely  alarmed  at  the  magnitude  of 
the  debt.  It  had  increased  during  the  thirteen  years  of 
Anne's  reign  over  200  per  cent.  The  debt  charge  had  risen 
from  about  £1,200,000  to  over  £3  million.  A  capital  levy 
was  being  seriously  urged.  It  was  imperative  that  steps 
be  taken  to  quiet  the  alarm  and  to  stop  this  discussion  about 
a  capital  levy  which  was  most  distasteful  to  the  moneyed 
classes.  Therefore,  Walpole  brought  forward  in  March,  1717, 
a  plan  for  a  sinking  fund.  Before  he  had  fairly  launched  this 
plan  there  was  a  change  in  the  Government  and  he  was  out 
of  the  Exchequer  for  four  years,  beginning  with  April,  1717. 
However,  his  plan  was  adopted  by  Stanhope,  his  successor, 
who  laid  proposals  before  Parliament  on  20th  May,  1717, 
which  led  to  legislation  appropriating  the  surplus  revenues  of 
the  Bank,  the  South  Sea  Company,  and  what  was  known  as  the 
General  Fund,  to  the  redemption  of  the  debt  incurred  prior 
to  25th  December,  1716. 

By  Christmas,  1727,  £6,626,000  of  this  old  debt  had  been 
retired,  but  in  the  interval  it  had  been  necessary  to  borrow 
new  money  so  that  the  debt  had  actually  increased  about 
£2  mini  on. 

Walpole,  with  all  his  ability  as  a  financier,  was  unwilling 
to  secure  a  radical  reduction  of  the  debt  by  imposing  worth- 
while taxation  for  that  purpose.     He  allowed  the  quarter  of 

101 


102  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

a  century  between  wars  to  pass  with  only  a  nominal  debt 
reduction.  After  1727  the  sinking  fund  became  inoperative 
for  debt  reduction,  the  funds  appropriated  to  it  being  diverted 
to  meeting  current  expenses,  in  order  that  the  taxation  of  the 
landed  classes  might  be  reduced.  However,  as  a  result  of 
successful  refunding  operations,  chiefly  in  connection  with  the 
South  Sea  Company's  operations  as  described  above,  the  debt 
charge  was  reduced  between  1714  and  1739,  by  no  less  a  sum 
than   £1   milhon. 

Pitt's  Sinking  Fund 

If  the  people  of  Walpole's  time  were  appalled  at  the  size 
of  the  debt,  those  hving  half  a  century  later  had  good  reason 
to  be  still  more  alarmed.  In  the  interval,  the  Seven  Years' 
War  and  the  American  War  had  raised  the  debt  fivefold  and 
the  debt  charge  nearly  in  the  same  proportion.  Therefore, 
after  putting  his  house  in  order  by  introducing  needed  reforms 
in  taxation  and  funding  the  floating  debt,  Pitt,  the  then 
Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  brought  forward,  in  1786,  a  plan 
for  a  sinking  fund  which,  within  a  period  of  forty-five  years, 
would  entirely  free  the  nation  from  debt. 

The  sinking  fund  was  to  be  a  sure  specific  against  the 
dangers  of  a  pubhc  debt.  In  fact  it  was  to  be  a  prophylactic 
which  would  make  it  quite  safe  on  occasion  to  increase  the 
debt.  This,  because  with  each  increase  of  debt  there  was  to 
be  an  increased  fund  with  which  to  insure  its  cancellation. 

One  milhon  pounds  a  year  was  to  be  taken  from  revenue 
and  paid  to  the  Commissioners  for  the  Reduction  of  the 
National  Debt,  in  whose  favour  also  the  existing  hfe  and 
terminable  annuities  were,  on  their  expiration,  to  be  con- 
tinued. The  Commissioners  were  to  invest  their  income 
from  all  sources  in  purchase  of  the  funded  debt,  until  the 
annual  sum  received  by  them  amounted  to  £4  million,  after 
which,  dividends  on  capital  stock  to  be  paid  off  by  them, 
and  any  hfe  and  terminable  annuities  which  should  mature, 
should  cease  and  be  considered  as  redeemed.  Subsequently 
;i(^400,000  a  year  was  added  to  the  fund  ;  also  a  sum  equal  to 


THE   SINKING  FUNDS  103 

the  interest  saved  by  any  reduction  of  interest  on  any 
redeemable  stock  ;  and  1  per  cent,  on  all  new  loans  issued 
for  public  purposes. 

Fallacy  of  Pitt's  Scheme 

It  is  difficult  to  understand  the  vogue  which  this  theory 
had  for  nearly  half  a  century. 

The  general  principle  that  money  placed  at  compound 
interest  will  double  itself  at  6  per  cent,  in  about  twelve  years, 
at  4  per  cent.,  in  about  eighteen  years,  and  so  on,  is  undeniable, 
but  the  error  lay  in  assuming  that  to  buy  up  and  "  keep  alive  " 
the  Nation's  own  obhgations  was  equivalent  to  placing  the 
funds  of  the  sinking  fund  at  interest. 

If  peace  had  continued  for  an  indefinite  period,  and  if  the 
additions  to  the  fund  had  scrupulously  been  made  from 
taxation  alone,  it  would  have  accomphshed  its  purpose.  But 
this  would  not  have  been  because  of  the  accumulations 
from  compound  interest,  but  because  an  amount,  determined 
by  such  calculations,  had  in  reality  been  taken  from  the 
people  in  the  form  of  taxation.  Strange  as  it  may  seem, 
most  of  the  brightest  intellects  of  the  day  were  confused 
on  this  matter.  If  England  could  have  placed  a  fund  in  some 
other  country,  or  in  Mars,  to  accumulate  at  compound 
interest,  the  theory  and  the  practice  would  have  been  in 
harmony.  So  long  as  the  fund  had  to  accumulate  at  home,  it 
was  all  one  whether  a  straight  annual  appropriation  for  the 
reduction  of  the  debt  were  made  from  revenue,  or,  an  appro- 
priation made  determined  by  the  circumlocution  of  the 
sinking  fund  legislation. 

However,  when,  as  happened  later,  the  Commissioners 
borrowed  money  for  the  sinking  fund,  instead  of  obtaining 
it  by  taxation,  and  when,  to  cap  the  cHmax,  they  paid  more 
for  this  borrowed  money  than  the  rate  of  interest  borne  by  the 
debt  redeemed,  the  situation  became  a  serious  one.  As  Tom 
Paine  tersely  and  humorously  put  the  case  in  one  of  his 
numerous  pamphlets  :  "  As  to  Mr.  Pitt's  project  of  paying  off 
the  National  Debt,  by  applying  a  miUion  a  year  for  that 


104  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

purpose,  while  he  continues  adding  more  than  £2Q  million  a 
year  to  it,  it  is  like  setting  a  man  with  a  wooden  leg  to  run 
after  a  hare.     The  longer  he  runs  the  farther  he  is  off." 

The  lesson  of  the  ineffectiveness  of  the  cumulative  sinking 
fund,  as  thus  administered,  was  not  learned  for  a  number  of 
years.  It  was  not  until  1829  that  this  fallacious  method  was 
finally  abandoned,  and  not  until  after  £322  milhon  had  been 
raised  at  an  average  cost  of  £5  Os.  6d.  per  cent,  per  annum,  to 
pay  off  debt  carrying  interest  at  £A  10s.  per  cent.  The 
difference  between  these  two  rates  is  10s.  6d.  per  cent,  per 
annum.  Therefore,  before  the  nation  awoke  to  its  folly  it 
had  increased  its  annual  fixed  debt  charge  for  this  purpose 
by  £1,690,000  ! 

Modem  Sinking  Funds 

Finally,  the  discovery  was  made  that  the  only  way  to  pay 
off  the  debt  was  from  an  excess  of  clear  revenue,  derived  from 
taxation,  over  the  expenditures  for  current  needs,  upon  which 
principle  the  sinking  fund  functioned  from  1829  to  1914. 
However,  the  reduction  in  debt  was  small  because  of  the 
unwiUingness  of  Parhament  to  make  any  substantial  appro- 
priations for  the  purpose.  The  terms  of  existing  sinking  funds 
are  given  in  notes,  following  the  National  Debt  Statement. 

In  1868,  and  again  in  1894,  the  plan  was  adopted  of 
issuing  terminable  annuities  in  lieu  of  funded  debt.  In 
1868,  £24  million  of  Savings  Bank  stock  was  cancelled  and 
an  annuity  of  £1,760,000  substituted,  while  in  1884,  Chancery 
stock  to  the  amount  of  £40  million  and  over  £30  million  of 
Post  Office  Savings  Bank  stock  were  similarly  treated.  Thus 
the  nominal  principal  of  the  debt  was  reduced  and  the  annual 
charge  increased,  just  reversing  the  South  Sea  Company 
operation  of  1720  and  before.  The  advantage  of  the  operation 
is  hard  to  find,  as  the  Government  of  course  remains  obligated 
to  the  Saving  Banks'  depositors  and  the  estates  in  Chancery 
for  the  full  amount  of  their  claims. 


CHAPTER  XIX 

EARLY   REFUNDING   OPERATIONS 

Reference  has  already  been  made,  in  discussing  the  affair 
of  the  South  Sea  Company,  to  the  refunding  operations 
prior  to  1739.  There  were  only  two  refunding  operations 
of  importance  between  1739  and  1817. 

Refunding  Operation  of  1749 — **  Consols  " 

Advantage  was  taken  of  the  period  of  peace  which  followed 
the  War  of  the  Austrian  Succession  to  take  measures  to 
reduce  the  interest  paid  on  the  debt  to  a  uniform  rate  of 
3  per  cent.  At  that  time  the  funded  debt,  apart  from  that 
due  to  the  Bank  of  England,  South  Sea  Company  and  East 
India  Company,  consisted  of  various  debts  contracted  at 
different  periods  under  several  Acts  of  Parhament  and 
charged  on  many  distinct  funds. 

Parhament  enacted  a  law  in  1749  that  all  pubhc  creditors 
at  4  per  cent,  should  be  paid  the  amount  of  their  holdings 
except  those  who  signified  their  consent  to  accept  3  per  cent, 
after  25th  December,  1757.  These  were  to  have  their 
present  interest  continued  until  25th  December,  1750,  and 
then  to  receive  3|  per  cent,  until  December,  1757.  The 
amount  of  these  debts,  including  those  due  to  the  Bank 
and  the  companies  was  £57,700,000.  The  greater  part  of 
the  creditors  accepted  the  proposition.  A  modified  offer,  not 
quite  so  favourable,  was  made  to  those  who  held  out  and  was 
generally  accepted,  with  the  result  that  the  Treasury  was 
called  upon  to  pay  off  only  about  £3  milUon.  As  a  result 
of  these  operations  and  the  payment  of  £3  miUion  navy  debt, 
there  was  a  net  decrease,  in  round  figures,  of  nearly  £5  million 
in  debt  before  the  outbreak  of  the  Seven  Years'  War  and  a 
reduction  in  the  annual  charge  of  ;^539,000.  As  an  indication 
of  the  state  of  the  national  credit  it  may  be  noted  that  the 
3  per  cents,  which  in   1748  sold  as  low  as  76  advanced  to 

105 


106  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

an  average  price  of  about  par  in  1749-1751,  and  upon  the 
successful  consummation  of  the  refunding  operations  sold  up 
to    106|  in    1752. 

The  success  of  this  operation  reflected  great  credit  upon 
the  administration.  It  also  gave  evidence  of  the  prosperous 
condition  of  the  country,  notwithstanding  the  long  war  which 
it  had  just  passed  through. 

In  the  session  of  1751-1752  an  act  was  passed  consohdating 
certain  of  the  3  per  cent,  issues  into  one  joint -stock  of  3  per 
cent,  annuities. 

Thus  originated  the  "  Consolidated  Annuities  "  or  "  Con- 
sols "  as  that  part  of  the  perpetual  debt  held  by  the  public 
has  ever  since  been  known. 

Funding  the  Floating  Debt  in  1784 

In  1784,  when  WiUiam  Pitt  the  younger  assumed  the 
duties  of  his  office  as  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  he  found 
outstanding  floating  debt  for  over  ;fl8  million,  chiefly  in 
the  form  of  navy  victualhng  and  transport  bills.  From  the 
time  of  Charles  II  the  payments  for  navy  victualling  and 
stores  had  been  made  in  bills  payable  at  uncertain  periods. 
They  were  taken  at  a  discount  which  increased  very  con- 
siderably at  every  time  of  war.  During  the  last  five  years 
of  the  American  War  this  discount  had  varied  from  11|  per 
cent,  to  16|  per  cent. 

Pitt  brought  about  legislation  by  which  the  Admiralty 
was  required  to  make  all  of  its  payments  in  bills  drawn 
at  ninety  days.  Thereafter,  as  these  bills  were  always 
discharged  with  rigid  punctuality  they  came  to  be  considered 
and  accepted  substantially  at  par,  with  a  resultant  large 
saving  to  the  Government. 

Of  the  navy  bills  outstanding  when  he  assumed  office,  Pitt 
funded  into  5  per  cent,  stock  £6,400,000  in  1785, and  ^^9,800,000 
in  1786,  giving  for  each  ;^100  debt  ;^107  10s.  6d.  in  the  first 
instance  and  ;^111  8s.  in  the  second.  Pitt  was  desirous  of 
completing  the  entire  transaction  in  1785,  but  in  deference  to 
the  views  of  the  bankers  spread  the  operation  over  two  years. 


EARLY   REFUNDING  OPERATIONS  107 

In  view  of  his  later  change  of  poUcy  in  that  respect  it  is  of 
interest  to  note  his  statement  to  Parhament,  "  that  a  fund  at 
a  high  rate  of  interest  is  better  to  the  country  than  those  at 
low  rates  ;  that  a  4  per  cent,  is  preferable  to  a  3  per  cent, 
and  a  5  per  cent,  better  than  a  4."  He  explains — "  the  reason 
is  that  in  all  operations  of  finance  we  should  always  have  in 
view  a  plan  of  redemption.  Gradually  to  redeem  and  to 
extinguish  our  debt  ought  ever  to  be  the  wise  pursuit  of 
government.  Every  scheme  and  operation  of  finance  should 
be  directed  to  that  end  and  managed  with  that  view." 

Competitive  Bidding  Inaugurated 

Former  ministers  had  made  the  placing  of  loans  a  source 
of  patronage.  Pitt  resolved  to  consult  the  pubhc  interest 
only.  He  gave  notice  through  the  Governor  and  the  Deputy- 
Governor  of  the  Bank  that  he  was  ready  to  contract  for  the 
loan  with  those  who  would  offer  the  lowest  terms.  Sealed 
tenders  were  required.  He  thus  established  a  salutary 
precedent  which  has  been  followed  in  connection  with  all 
subsequent  loans  not  offered  at  fixed  prices.  It  may  be 
noted  in  passing  that  the  purchasing  of  army  supphes  was 
placed  by  him  on  a  similar  competitive  basis,  thus  ending 
scandalous  practices  of  long  standing. 


CHAPTER  XX 

FINANCING  THE   GREAT   FRENCH   WAR 
(1793-1817) 

The  outbreak  of  the  French  Revolution  in  1789,  leading 
up  to  the  atrocities  of  1792,  which  culminated  in  the  execution 
of  Louis  XVI  on  the  morning  of  21st  January,  1793,  ushered 
in  a  period  of  internal  strife  and  of  foreign  wars  such  as  France 
and  the  world  had  never  before  experienced.  With  the 
declarations  of  war  by  France  in  February,  1793,  against 
England,  Holland  and  Spain,  the  period  of  peace  which 
England  had  enjoyed  since  the  American  War  and  the  hope 
of  a  further  similar  period  was  abruptly  ended.  The  adminis- 
tration found  themselves  face  to  face  with  a  foreign  war, 
while  for  some  time  they  had  been  compelled  to  deal  with 
dangerous  uprisings  at  home.  Thus  ended  a  period  of  nine 
years,  perhaps  one  of  the  most  prosperous  and  happy  that 
England  had  ever  known.  It  had  not  been  a  period  of 
prosperity  for  all  classes,  because  the  radical  changes  in  the 
conditions  of  the  industrial  and  agricultural  classes  had  brought 
cruel  hardships  to  many.  However,  taking  the  country  as  an 
entirety,  it  had  been  a  time  of  decided  progress.  This  period 
of  prosperity  terminated  in  a  severe  financial  crisis  and  con- 
sequent "  hard  times."  A  succession  of  bad  harvests  caused 
a  scarcity  of  food  and  resultant  high  prices.  Throughout 
the  commercial  world  the  war  was  preceded  by  "a  great 
revulsion  and  derangement  of  commercial  credit."  There 
were  many  failures  of  mercantile  houses,  while  no  less  than 
twenty-six  country  banks  were  forced  to  close  their  doors. 
In  April,  1793,  the  distress  became  so  acute  that  the  Govern- 
ment found  it  necessary  to  apply  extraordinary  remedial 
measures.  At  a  meeting  of  merchants  held  at  the  Mansion 
House  on  the  23rd  of  April  it  was  voted  to  apply  to  Mr.  Pitt 
to  advance  Exchequer  Bills  on  the  security  of  goods  and 
merchandise  and  other  property.     The  request  was  referred 

108 


FINANCING  THE   GREAT   FRENCH   WAR  109 

to  Parliament  and  on  the  29th  of  April,  Exchequer  Bills  to 
the  extent  of  £5  million  were  ordered  applied  to  advances. 
This  measure  proved  to  be  very  successful  in  allaying  fear 
and  distrust.  The  fact  that  assistance  could  be  obtained  if 
needed  made  it  unnecessary  in  most  cases  to  ask  for  it. 

The  Loan  of  1793 

It  was  in  such  a  market  as  this  that  William  Pitt  was  com- 
pelled to  arrange  for  his  first  war  loan  of  £4,500,000.  This 
loan  was  obtained  by  a  sale  of  3  per  cent,  consols  at  72, 
making  the  money  cost  about  4^^  per  cent,  per  annum. 

The  effect  of  the  business  crisis  had  been  to  carry  down 
the  price  of  consols  from  quotations  of  around  90  which  had 
been  current  during  August,  September  and  October,  1792, 
to  below  80  in  the  latter  part  of  November.  Quotations  in 
January,  1793,  had  averaged  about  75.  Upon  the  declara- 
tion of  war  they  broke  to  72  and  under,  so  that  Pitt's  bargain 
was  a  fair  one  for  the  Exchequer,  although  prices  rallied 
almost  immediately  to  around  77  and  did  not  go  below  74 
during  the  rest  of  the  year.  The  choice  of  the  3  per  cents., 
while  contrary  to  Pitt's  previously  expressed  preference  for 
stocks  at  higher  interest  rates  and  therefore  seUing  nearer 
to  par,  was  fully  justified  by  the  fact  that  thus  a  better  bargain 
for  the  Exchequer  could  be  made,  as  the  fours  and  fives  were 
seUing  relatively  much  lower — ^that  is,  on  a  higher  interest 
basis. 

The  war  thus  entered  upon  lasted  until  the  middle  of  the 
year  1801,  although  the  formal  signing  of  the  articles  of  peace 
at  Amiens  did  not  take  place  until  March,  1802. 

The  war  ended  in  a  draw.  One  by  one  the  other  antago- 
nists dropped  out  until  England  and  France  alone  were 
involved.  Each  nation  was  ready  for  a  cessation  of  hostihties. 
Nothing  had  been  decided,  and,  in  the  settlement,  Great  Britain 
gave  up  practically  all  acquisitions  of  territory  which  she 
had  made.  Great  Britain  expended  during  the  nine  years 
about  £420  miUion,  60  per  cent,  of  which  represented  the  cost 
of  maintaining  the  army  and  navy,  against  a  normal  peace 


110  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

expenditure  of  about  one-fifth  of  this  amount.  The  interest 
and  management  of  the  debt  absorbed  another  30  per  cent, 
so  that  over  90  per  cent,  of  the  expenditure  of  the  period  may 
be  said  to  have  been  due  to  war — ^past  and  current .  Of  this 
great  sum,  which  was  twice  the  average  expenditure  during 
the  period  of  the  "  extravagant  "  American  War,  55'60 
per  cent,  was  raised  by  taxation  and  the  remainder  by 
borrowing. 

The  Loyalty  Loan  of  1796 

During  this  period  there  were  eighteen  different  loan 
negotiations.  We  have  seen  that  the  first  loan  was  placed  at 
a  little  over  4  per  cent.  In  1794,  1795,  and  the  early  part 
of  1796,  it  was  necessary  to  pay  over  4^  per  cent.  In  Decem- 
ber, 1796,  the  money  cost  over  5J  per  cent.,  while  in  1797 
and  1798  it  cost  from  6^  to  6|  per  cent.  In  1799  and  1801, 
5|  per  cent,  was  paid,  but  in  1800  over  £20  miUion  was 
secured  at  about  4|  per  cent.  Most  of  the  loans  were  issued 
as  threes  with  annuity  bonuses  and  in  some  cases  with  a 
percentage  in  fours.  The  rate  on  Navy  and  Victualhng  Bills, 
issued  as  fives  repayable  after  relatively  short  periods,  was 
substantially  higher  than  that  paid  on  the  annuities.  The 
average  actual  rate  paid  on  all  loans,  long  and  short,  was 
almost  exactly  5J  per  cent. 

The  Loyalty  Loan  issued  in  December,  1796,  was  offered 
for  pubhc  subscription,  books  being  opened  at  the  Bank.  It 
was  a  year  of  great  difficulty.  The  progress  of  the  war  had 
been  discouraging.  There  had  been  a  run  on  the  Bank 
threatening  the  suspension  of  specie  payments  which  took 
place  in  February  of  the  following  year,  and  symptoms  of 
discontent  had  appeared  in  the  army.  Under  these  circum- 
stances, with  the  pressure  of  taxation  keenly  felt,  the  ministry 
believed  that  a  resort  to  the  ordinary  methods  of  raising  a 
loan  would  be  perilous.  It  was  determined,  therefore,  to 
throw  the  subscription  open  to  the  public  and  to  appeal  to 
the  patriotism  of  the  country. 

This  course  was  fully  justified  by  the  outcome.     Within 


FINANCING   THE   GREAT   FRENCH   WAR  111 

fifteen  hours  the  entire  £18  milhon  was  over-subscribed. 
However,  the  loan  was  at  4  per  cent,  discount  before  the 
payment  of  the  deposit.  This  discount  afterward  became 
8  per  cent,  and  finally  14  per  cent.,  but  every  payment  was 
duly  made. 

Final  Period  (1803-1815) 

Such  a  peace  as  that  signed  at  Amiens  was  not  destined 
to  be  permanent.  British  statesmen  felt  that  it  was  danger- 
ous to  give  such  an  antagonist  as  Napoleon  time  in  which  to 
grow  strong.  They  therefore  took  advantage  of  a  dispute  in 
regard  to  the  disposition  of  Malta  to  renew  the  war  in  May, 
1803,  and  thus  to  arrive  at  a  settlement  which  would  be  con- 
clusive. Notwithstanding  the  fact  that  they  caught  Napoleon 
unprepared,  the  war  proved  to  be  one  of  long  duration. 
The  burdens  which  it  imposed  in  the  form  of  taxation  and 
debt,  deranged  industrial  conditions  and  unsettled  commerce 
were  tremendous.  It  has  been  said  that  it  was  a  war  of  the 
Enghsh  people  rather  than  of  great  leaders.  Pitt,  who  had 
dominated  the  first  period,  was  out  of  office  when  hostiUties 
were  renewed.  Although  temporarily  called  back  under  the 
stressed  conditions  of  1804,  he  had  only  been  at  the  head  of 
the  Government  a  couple  of  years  when  he  died  in  1806, 
brokenhearted  at  Napoleon's  apparent  invincibleness.  Thus 
we  find  no  one  master  mind  dictating  the  financing  of  this 
period. 

The  Cost  of  the  War 

During  the  second  period  of  the  war,  terminated  by  the 
treaty  of  Paris,  signed  20th  November,  1815,  the  annual 
expense  just  about  doubled  that  of  the  first  period.  Elim- 
inating an  estimated  normal  expense  based  upon  the  budgets 
of  the  last  preceding  peace  period  the  average  annual  war 
expense  of  the  first  period  of  the  war  was  approximately 
£28  miUion  and  of  the  second  period  £62  million. 

Taking  the  entire  period  of  twenty-three  years  of  war  into 
consideration  the  total  cost  in  round  figures  was  about  £1,200 

RETURN   TQ- 

BUREAU  CF  INTERKATICNAL  RELATK^^ 

384   LIBRARY   ANNEX 
UNIVERSITY  OF  CALIFORNIA?. 


112  ENGLISH    PUBLIC   FINANCE 

million,  a  yearly  average  of  £52,150,000.  This  total  is 
accounted  for  as  follows  :  Direct  increased  military  and  naval 
expenditure,  ;f826,223,000,  increased  cost  of  civil  government 
;^111,212  000,  increased  debt  charge  £262,077,000.  The 
extraordinary  expenses  of  1816  are  included  in  these  figures 
as  the  accounts  of  this  year  were  still  considerably  affected 
by  the  aftermath  of  the  war.  In  making  estimates  such  as 
this,  most  writers  include  only  the  direct  military  expense. 
This  manifestly  leads  to  an  underestimate.  The  increased 
cost  of  civil  government  due  to  the  war  conditions  should 
surely  be  taken  into  consideration  and  there  should  be  no 
difference  of  opinion  as  to  the  propriety  of  including 
the  increased  burden  of  the  national  debt,  to  the  extent 
that  the  increase  in  debt  is  caused  by  the  financing  of  the 
war. 

It  is  unfortunately  true  that  with  each  recurring  war 
there  is  not  only  a  permanent  addition  to  the  debt  charge,  but 
also  to  the  cost  of  civil  government,  while  the  military 
expenditure  rises  to  a  new  level. 

Furthermore,  each  recurring  war  costs  more  for  each  year 
of  war  than  does  its  predecessor.  The  first  three  wars  oc- 
curring after  the  Revolution  cost  on  the  average  £4  million 
sterling,  for  each  year  of  war  ;  the  next,  £12  million  ;  the  next, 
£13  million  ;  the  first  part  of  the  Great  French  War,  £28 
million,  and  the  last,  £62  million.  The  two  other  great  wars 
of  England  preceding  the  greatest  of  all  which  has  just  ended 
— namely,  the  Crimean  and  the  Boer  Wars — cost  on  the 
average,  respectively,  £24  and  £70  million  for  each  year  of 
war.  This  is  not  a  place  to  moralize,  but  the  mere  statement 
of  the  facts  alone  is  an  eloquent  indictment  of  war  as  a  method 
of  setthng  international  disputes.  How  frequently  we  find 
upon  the  conclusion  of  a  war  that  the  articles  of  peace  in  no 
way  refer  to  the  ostensible  cause  of  the  war.  Still,  if  ever  a 
war  was  really  justified,  this  twenty-three-year  war  of  Eng- 
land's was  such  a  one — the  first  part  of  it  a  stand  against 
the  spectre  of  world  anarchy  and  the  second  against  the 
overweening  ambition  and  autocratic  plans  of  Napoleon. 


FINANCING   THE    GREAT  FRENCH  WAR  113 

The  Cost  Met  from  Taxation 

The  financing  of  the  war  covered  the  Exchequer  period 
from  10th  October,  1793,  to  5th  January,  1817.  It  is  im- 
possible to  give  the  statistics  with  absolute  accuracy,  as  in  1801 
a  change  took  place  in  the  method  of  stating  the  accounts. 
Prior  to  that  date  the  returns  are  on  a  "  net  "  basis — ^that  is, 
the  cost  of  collection  and  management  of  the  revenues  is 
deducted  therefrom.  Thereafter  the  gross  revenue  is  given 
and  the  expenses  of  collection  are  stated  on  the  other  side 
of  the  account.  The  returns  are  said  to  be  on  a  "gross" 
basis.  Therefore,  for  part  of  the  period  under  review  we 
have  "  net  "  returns  and  for  part  "  gross  "  returns.  How- 
ever, this  fact  does  not  seriously  interfere  with  securing  a 
review  of  the  finance  of  the  period. 

The  striking  thing  to  note  is  that  eUminating  all  items 
having  to  do  with  the  debt,  the  other  expenses  were  entirely 
met  from  revenue  collections.  The  expenses  of  civil  govern- 
ment averaged  ;f6,708,000  a  year  and  the  mihtary  expenses 
£39,213,000,  an  aggregate  of  about  £46  million.  The  revenue 
receipts  averaged  £49,575,000  a  year  ;  or,  taking  the  aggre- 
gate figures  for  the  twenty-four  years,  civil  and  mihtary 
expenses  were  £1,117,656,000  and  revenue  receipts  were 
£1,202,195,000. 

It  was  during  this  time  that  pamphlets  without  number 
were  being  issued  from  the  press  in  regard  to  the  debt,  its 
great  and  growing  burden,  the  necessity  for  the  cost  of  wars 
being  met  by  the  generation  which  carried  them  on  and  the 
blessings  and  operations  of  the  sinking  fund. 

The  borrowing  which  took  place  provided  the  means  for 
temporarily  bridging  gaps  between  expenditure  and  revenue, 
for  meeting  the  interest  charge  on  the  inherited  debt  and  for 
feeding  the  sinking  fund  which,  strange  to  say,  was  adding  to 
the  debt  instead  of  reducing  it .  For  the  twenty-four  years  the 
charge  for  the  interest  and  management  of  the  debt  was 
£511,306,000— £227,655,000  on  account  of  pre-war  debt  and 
£283,651,000  on  account  of  new  debt. 

8— (1823) 


114 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


The  operations  on  account  of  the  debt  ran  into  heavy 
figures  as  will  be  seen  from  an  examination  of  this  table. 

SUMMARY   OF   DEBT   OPERATIONS. 

Great  French  Wars. 

October,  1792 — February,  1817. 

In  Millions  Sterling. 


Money  Values. 

Credits. 

Debits. 

Gross  amount  borrowed      ..... 

Disposition — 

Debt  paid  off 

Interest  and  management  on  new  or  war  debt 
Net  benefit  to  Exchequer  from  war  borrowings 

£ 

1,315 

£ 

881 
283 
151 

1,315 

1,315 

Thus  the  net  benefit  to  the  Exchequer  from  net  borrowings 
of  £434  million,  money  values,  was  only  £151  million,  11^  per 
cent,  of  the  gross  amount  borrowed,  sufficient  with,  say,  £77 
million  from  revenue  to  pay  the  charge  of  £227,655,000  for 
the  pre-war  debt. 

In  1793  the  total  debt  was  £239,663.000.  On  the  5th  of 
January,  1817,  it  was  £850  million,  an  increase  of  £610,337,000 
— par  value.  The  debt  charge  meanwhile  had  increased 
£22,623,000,  from  £9,432,000  to  £32,055,000.  Mr.  Chisholm 
in  his  monumental  report  on  the  debt,  estimates  that  of  the  net 
amount  borrowed  during  this  period  about  one-third — say, 
£192,868,000 — was  required  for  the  sinking  fund.  The  annual 
charge  for  interest  on  the  new  money  borrowed  was  £5  3s.  9d. 
per  cent.,  while  the  similar  charge  on  the  debt  redeemed  by 
the  sinking  fund  was  £4  16s.  8d.  per  cent.  The  difference 
between  the  two  rates  of  interest,  equal  to  7s.  Id.  per  cent., 
is  the  annual  amount  lost  by  the  sinking  fund  operations 
on  the  £192,868,000  redeemed  ;  or,  at  the  rate  of  about 
£683,000  added  fixed  charge  per  annum. 

Debt  V.  National  Wealth 

The  burden  of  the  debt  upon  the  community,  while  heavy. 


FINANCING  THE   GREAT   FRENCH  WAR  115 

was  by  no  means    "  crushing,"    a  term  by  which    it    has 
frequently  been  described. 

The  per  capita  debt  was  about  ;f50  sterUng,  or  not  quite 
one-third  of  the  estimated  per  capita  national  wealth.  At 
the  close  of  the  American  War,  another  period  when  the 
debt  was  "  crushing,"  the  per  capita  amount  was  estimated 
at  about  £2d  and  the  debt  at  about  25  per  cent .  of  the  national 
wealth.    These  estimates  all  deal  with  par  values. 

Debt  Charge  v.  National  Income 

On  account  of  the  pohcy  of  discount  financing  pursued  in 
the  negotiation  of  loans,  a  better  way  to  judge  of  the  actual 
burden  of  the  debt  is  to  institute  a  comparison  between  the 
annual  charge  for  interest  and  maintenance  and  the  estimated 
national  income.  The  growth  in  national  income  had  been 
very  great  since  the  beginning  of  the  American  War  in  1775. 
At  that  time  the  national  income  was  estimated  to  be  ;^100 
million.  At  the  close  of  that  war  an  increase  of  about  25  per 
cent,  is  estimated  to  have  taken  place.  At  the  beginning 
of  the  Great  French  Wars  the  people  of  England  were  probably 
in  receipt  of  an  aggregate  income  of  £160  million.  So  far 
our  estimates  apply  only  to  England  and  Wales.  In  1802 
we  may  add  Scotland  and,  too,  we  are  now  deahng  with  more 
rehable  figures,  as  we  begin  to  have  the  income  tax  returns  as 
a  basis.  We  seem  to  be  warranted  in  accepting  an  estimate 
of  £230  million  for  the  national  income  at  this  date.  At 
the  close  of  the  Napoleonic  wars  in  1815  we  have  an  estimated 
income  for  the  17  million  people  of  the  United  Kingdom 
of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  of  £400  milhon. 

It  is  beheved  these  estimates  fairly  reflect  the  facts,  for  we 
know,  notwithstanding  the  toll  of  the  wars,  that  the  popula- 
tion had  been  rapidly  increasing  ;  also  commerce,  as  evidenced 
by  the  increase  in  shipping  and  in  the  values  of  exported  and 
imported  goods  ;  also  the  volume  of  business,  as  evidenced  by 
the  steady  increase  in  the  yield  of  the  income  tax  and  the  fact 
that  the  people  at  the  same  time  were  able  to  pay  the 
enormous  excise  taxes. 


H 

K 

di 

H 

"< 

s 

<o 

o 

•2 

H 

H 

W 

Ik 

o 

8 

CA 

M 

Q 

g 

r ) 

Z 

o 

a 

w 

-*; 

m 

u 

^ 

» 

« 

PM 

s 

o      . 

o 

w 

H     t<« 

« 

w 

en    00 

>, 

H 

0    '-' 

O 

2     00 
U     CO 

13 
S 
B 

^0 

55 

tJ 

Q 

M 

■< 

^ 

Q 

o 

VJ 

o 

"^ 

H 

W 

M 

Ki 

w 

w 

e 

o 

o 

p« 

"3 

< 

<^ 

> 

^ 

Ik 

O 

H 

CO 

Q 

h^ 

O 

H 

» 

H 

H 

< 

Charge 

Per 

Cent. 

s 

o 
o 

a 

oooiccocjoecQOi/^cc—i 

qO  COC£!C^q5'^-*<X>C£>Q0 

00  00 

Charge 

per 
Capita. 

^^irtinc^t^'-'OO'^c^cc— ' 

cc  t^ 

National 
Annual 
Income. 

1 

Ah   S' 

"M^oo  ooooooooccmoo 

ooo 

t-(  1-1 
(N  (N 

13 
o 
H 

W««DO-<l'tW50inO 

OO 

cn  o 

Average 

Interest 

Rate. 

-cot>i00r^oo<3ncmoo 
^^  ooc<)^05-*cciipq)0> 

t^t^co-'i'eocccocceccc 

00  t^ 

CO  ec 

Change 

from 

Previous 

Period.* 

>~<  00         C<l  «0  N  *4  0^.  *» 

0"(N 

■'-'  h 
o  rt 

^6 

CO  C^  O  0_C<1_<0_QO_CD  liO  CO 

'"♦^i-T  ^  c6  c^"  cc  c^*  ■*  -*"  Oi  Oi 

OOO 

oTn" 

-1  cc 

^1 

;2l 

^. '—_  c^_  co_  o  c^_  <x  <n  CM  r«._ 
UtT  i/s"  id"  1/5  CD  cc  co"  r>  oo"  oo" 

oo 

i-ri> 

•a 
a 
W 

<DO  —  eO-^UDCDt^QOOl 

g*  ::::::   :o    : 
0.    ::::::   :oo 

o  ^ 

00  00 

a    : 

•— ) 

Period. 

.        .    .   1 

Wars  of  WilUam  III 

Peace 

Wars  of  Anne 

Peace 

Spanish- Austrian  Wars 

Peace 

Seven  Years'  War 

Peace 

American  War 

Peace 

Great  French  War — 

1st  Period      . 

2nd  Period    . 

rt  M 


4> 

a  o5 

t^s? 

+j 

rt 

13 

*      4) 

o 

O 

0) 

rn 

rt 

^ 

(fl 

C  d 

•IH 

rt  +j 

-t->   ^ 

a 

O   C 

3 

W 

o 
u 

ns 

CO 

rt  ^ 

-t-> 

0  o 

fl 

ct)  fl 

fl 

> 

•a 

fl^ 

to 

c 

d 

lU 

o 

60 

a! 

n1 

>^e 

,a 

c  9 

o 

o« 

n 

tj  c 

i> 

fl-" 

T3 

u  rt  g 

[5 

«  O  <u 

FINANCING  THE   GREAT  FRENCH   WAR  117 

Therefore  we  seem  to  be  justified  in  accepting  them  as  a 
measure  of  the  burden  of  the  debt  at  the  times  indicated  and 
of  its  comparative  weight.  So  we  arrive  at  the  interesting 
summary  statement  contained  in  the  table  on  page  116.  In 
interpreting  this  table  the  fact  should  not  be  lost  sight  of  that 
the  purchasing  power  of  money  has  varied  considerably 
during  the  two  and  a  third  centuries.  The  relative  burden 
of  the  debt  cannot  be  judged  merely  by  comparative 
statistics  in  terms  of  money.  If  we  had  index  numbers  of 
prices  such  as  exist  to-day  covering  the  entire  period  and  could 
adjust  money  values  accordingly  we  would  probably  discover 
that  to-day's  burden  is  relatively  not  materially  greater  than 
at  other  crucial  periods. 

This  table  demonstrates  in  a  striking  manner  why  it  was, 
notwithstanding  all  the  direful  prophecies  of  disaster  which 
were  made  at  all  of  these  periods,  that  after  each  war  England 
shook  herself  hke  a  great  ship  coming  up  out  of  the  trough  of  a 
stormy  sea  and  went  on  her  way  unscathed.  That  reason 
was  because,  although  one  of  the  oldest  of  the  nations,  she 
was  nevertheless  full  of  vitahty  and  rapidly  growing  in  popu- 
lation and  in  material  resources.  Students  of  this  period 
point  out  that  because  of  the  integrity  of  property  and  con- 
tracts in  England,  she  became  to  an  important  degree  during 
the  Great  War  the  custodian  of  the  savings  of  Europe.  Thus 
she  was  enabled  to  finance  her  trade  on  an  ever  increasing 
scale  as  well  as  to  finance  the  stupendous  costs  of  the  twenty- 
three  years  of  war.  Sowing  and  reaping  in  national  finance 
is  thus  illustrated. 

Another  moral  phase  of  the  situation  which  cannot  be 
tabulated  but  which  is  at  the  base  of  England's  credit 
structure,  is  that  not  once  apparently  was  there  even  a 
thought  of  repudiation — even  when  the  burden  of  debt 
pressed  heaviest.  Fears  there  were  plenty  of  the  abihty 
of  the  nation  to  continue  to  meet  its  obhgations,  but  never 
once  a  suggestion  of  trying  to  get  rid  of  the  obligations  in  any 
other  way  than  the  good  old-fashioned  one  of  paying. 


CHAPTER  XXI 

REVENUE  AND  EXPENDITURE 
(1688-1817) 

During  the  centuries  which  preceded  the  EngHsh  Revolution 
of  1688,  the  Enghshman  had  held  the  reins  over  his  auto- 
cratic rulers  and  had  finally  won  a  state  of  comparative 
political  freedom  by  his  control  of  the  purse. 

The  King's  hereditary  revenues  were  passed  on  from  one 
sovereign  to  the  next,  also  those  of  which  it  was  customary  for 
Parhament  to  make  a  life  grant  at  the  beginning  of  each  reign. 
However,  Parliament  retained  absolute  control  over  other 
sources  of  revenue  which  it  voted  from  year  to  year.  Thus, 
by  making  it  necessary  for  the  King  to  call  them  together  to 
vote  at  least  a  pcirt  of  the  supplies,  the  Commons  were  able 
to  control,  to  some  extent  at  least,  the  acts  of  the  King. 

When  William  HI  consented  to  assume  the  responsibihties 
of  the  throne  in  1688  he  expected  that  the  usual  grants  would 
be  made  to  him.  To  this  Parhament  in  part  demurred.  No 
change  was  made  in  respect  of  the  hereditary  revenues,  but 
Parliament  declined  to  make  the  usual  life  grants.  Instead, 
the  revenues  usually  so  granted  were  made  renewable  at  the 
end  of  four  years. 

Thus  was  confirmed,  or  more  properly  reasserted,  the 
principle  of  a  short  grant  of  some  considerable  branch  of  the 
revenue  with  a  view  to  keeping  the  sovereign  dependent 
upon  the  will  of  Parhament . 

It  is  not  our  purpose  to  consider  in  detail  the  various  forms 
of  State  expenditure,  nor  do  we  intend  to  take  up  in  detail 
the  methods  of  raising  revenue  during  the  period  under 
review. 

Purposes  of  Expenditure 

The  broad  general  purposes  of  expenditure  were,  as  they 
are  to-day,  the  expenses  of  civil  government,  the  expense  of 

118 


REVENUE  AND  EXPENDITURE  119 

the  maintenance  of  the  military  establishment  and  the  charge 
for  the  interest  upon  the  national  debt. 

An  inspection  of  the  table  on  page  120  will  show  how 
these  expenses  grew  from  one  historical  period  to  another. 

The  table  is  arranged  to  show  the  average  annual  expen- 
diture for  each  period  of  peace  and  of  war  from  the  Revolution 
until  the  end  of  the  French  wars,  and  for  the  peace  period 
immediately  following. 

The  important  facts  to  notice  are  the  progressive  increasing 
expense  of  each  war  period  and  the  fact  that  after  each 
war  the  level  of  peace  expenditure  is  raised. 

The  Growing  Burden 

It  will  be  observed  that  the  war  period  of  the  reign  of 
Wilham  III  cost  on  the  average  about  £5  million  a  year. 
The  mihtaristic  administration  of  Anne  cost  half  as  much 
again.  During  the  Seven  Years'  War  the  expenses  were 
double  those  of  Queen  Anne's  reign.  During  the  American 
War  they  were  50  per  cent,  higher  than  during  the  Seven 
Years'  War.  For  the  first  part  of  the  Great  French  War  the 
expenses  were  double  those  of  the  American  War  period, 
while  the  expenses  of  the  last  part  of  the  French  War  averaged 
nearly  twice  those  of  the  first  part.  With  these  figures 
in  mind  let  us  now  turn  to  the  record  of  the  intervening  peace 
periods.  Here  we  find  this  interesting  sequence — we  will  use 
round  figures.  Following  the  peace  of  Ryswick  in  1697, 
the  average  annual  budget  was  ^^3,800,000  ;  after  the  peace 
of  Utrecht  in  1713,  about  £5,700,000  ;  after  the  peace  of 
Aix  la  Chapelle  in  1748,  £6,600,000  ;  following  the  peace 
of  Paris  in  1763,  £9,900,000  ;  after  the  peace  of  Versailles 
in  1783,  £16,600,000  ;  while  looking  ahead  into  the  next 
period  we  find  that  for  the  years  immediately  following  the 
peace  of  Paris  in  1815,  peace  expenses  rose  to  a  new  level 
of  £56  million  a  year. 

It  is  true  that  a  most  important  part  of  the  growing  cost 
of  government  was  due  to  the  cumulative  effect  of  the  charge 
for  the  growing  public  debt.     Again  it  seemed  to  be  considered 


120 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 


necessary  after  each  war  to  maintain  the  military  establish- 
ment on  a  new  level  of  expenditure.  Still,  even  the  expense 
of  civil  government,  the  strictly  peace  establishment,  exhibited 
the  same  tendency  to  expand.     The  table  follows — 


GOVERNMENT  EXPENDITURES,   1688-1830. 

Average  per  Annum  for  Alternate  Periods  of  War  and  Peace. 

In  Millions  Sterling. 


Period. 

Character  of  Period. 

Peace. 

War. 

i 

I 

1688-1697 

Wars  of  William  III          .          .          . 

5.1 

1698-1701 

Peace 

3,8 

— 

1702-1714 

Wars  of  Anne 

— 

7,6 

1715-1739 

Peace 

5,7 

— 

1740-1749 

Spanish- Austrian  Wars 

— 

9,5 

1750-1755 

Peace 

6,6 

— 

1756-1766 

Seven  Years'  War  , 

— 

14,5 

1767-1775 

Peace 

9.9 

— 

1776-1785 

American  War 

— 

21,8 

1786-1792 

Peace 

16,6 

— 

1793-1802 

1st  Period— Great  French  War 

— 

45,4 

1803-1817 

2nd  Period — Great  French  War 

— 

80,5 

1818-1830 

Peace     ..... 

56,2 

— 

Sources  of  Income 

Let  us  now  turn  to  the  other  side  of  the  account  and  see 
from  what  sources  the  income  was  derived  with  which  to 
meet  these  constantly  growing  expenditures.  Here  we  have 
some  surprises  awaiting  us,  particularly  when  we  come  to  the 
period  of  the  Great  French  War.  Again  we  will  deal  with 
the  average  annual  figures,  as  this  is  the  only  way  in  which  we 
can  make  a  comparative  study.  Taking  first  the  revenue 
from  other  sources  than  borrowing,  we  find  that  the  excise 
taxes  were  most  productive,  then  the  customs  and  then  the 
land  and  house  duties.  The  stamp  taxes  first  began  to  be  of 
importance  in  the  period  following  the  American  War.  During 
the  second  part  of  the  Great  French  War  the  income  tax 
assumed  great  importance,  yielding  almost  as  much  as  the 
customs. 


REVENUE  AND   EXPENDITURE 


121 


Now  we  come  to  the  interesting  and  surprising  phase 
of  the  situation.  From  the  stress  which  has  been  put 
upon  the  growth  of  the  debt  it  might  be  assumed  that 
the  greater  part  of  the  cost  of  the  wars  and  of  the  growing 
expenses  of  all  kinds  had  been  obtained  by  mortgaging 
the  future.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  just  the  reverse  is  true. 
Most  surprising  of  all,  the  really  stupendous  expenses  of 
the  Napoleonic  War — ^the  second  half  of  the  Great  French 
War  period — were  met  chiefly  from  taxation,  the  exact 
percentages  being  79-70  from  taxation  and  20"30  from 
borrowing. 

The  table  of  Government  income  following,  prepared  to 
cover  the  same  historical  periods  as  in  the  case  of  the 
Expenditure  table,  may  be  studied  with  profit. 


GOVERNMENT  REVENUE   1688-1830. 

Average  per  Annum  for  Alternate  Periods  of  War  and  Peace 

In  Millions  Sterling. 


Peace. 

War. 

Period. 

Character  of  Period. 

Tax. 

Tax. 

Debt. 

Total. 

Tax. 

Debt. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

% 

%» 

1688-1697 

Wars  of  William  III 

3,6 

1,8 

6.4 

66-43 

33-56 

1698-1701 

Peace 

4,6 

— 

— 

— 

— 

— 

1702-1714 

Wars  of  Aniie 

5,4 

2,3 

7.7 

69-55 

30-40 

1715-1739 

Peace 

5.9 

— 

— 

— 

— 

— 

1740-1749 

Spanish- Austrian 

Wars    . 

— 

6,6 

3,0 

9.6 

68-91 

31-08 

1750-1755 

Peace 

7,1 

— 

— 

— 

— 

— 

1756-1766 

Seven  Years  War      . 

9,1 

5,5 

14,6 

62-62 

37-37 

1767-1775 

Peace 

loT? 

— 

— 

— 

— 

1776-1785 

American  War 

— 

12,7 

9,4 

22.1 

57-39 

42-61 

1786-1792 

Peace 

17,0 

— 

— 

— 

— 

— 

1793-1802 

1st  Period   \  French 
2nd  Period  /  War 

26,2 

20,9 

47.1 

55-60 

44-40 

1803-1817 

— 

64,4 

16,4 

80,8 

79-70 

20-30 

1818-1830 

Peace 

68,0 

■"" 

_. 

*"" 

~ 

CHAPTER  XXII 

PEACE   AND   SOCIAL   BETTERMENT 
(1817-1914) 

We  have  just  been  studying  the  finances  of  a  period  the 
dominating  note  in  which  was  war.  It  was  also  the  period 
when  the  greater  part  of  the  English  debt,  as  it  stood  prior 
to  the  recent  world  cataclysm,  was  created.  We  now  enter 
upon  the  study  of  a  period  where  peace  was  dominant. 
During  the  century  there  were  two  important  wars  and  a 
number  of  military  expeditions,  but  as  these  were  all  fought 
at  a  distance,  they  scarcely  interrupted  the  course  of  events  at 
home. 

The  period  is  one  of  intense  interest  to  the  social  reformer, 
to  the  economist  and  to  the  pubhcist.  For  the  student  of 
public  finance  it  is  chiefly  memorable  as  a  time  within  which 
the  methods  of  taxation  were  greatly  simplified.  A  dis- 
tinguished succession  of  finance  ministers,  notably  Peel, 
Disraeli  and  Gladstone,  introduced  and  successfully  established 
innovations  in  State  finance  of  far-reaching  importance. 

Sources  of  Revenue — ^Tariff  Reform 

During  this  period  England  was  transformed  from  a  country 
surrounded  by  high  tariff  walls  to  one  practising  free  trade 
in  its  most  extreme  form.  From  the  standpoint  of  finance 
this  resulted  in  reducing  the  number  of  classes  of  commodities 
upon  which  customs  duties  were  collected  from  1200  in 
1842  to  466  in  1853,  and  to  only  48  in  1860.  By  1880  the 
number  of  classes  of  articles  upon  the  tariff  had  been  reduced 
to  10.  In  1914  substantially  the  entire  customs  revenue  was 
derived,  in  the  order  named,  from  tobacco,  tea  and  sugar  and 
from  spirits  in  various  forms,  including  motor  spirits;  although 
cocoa  and  its  preparations,  and  coffee,  together  yielded  a 

122 


PEACE   AND   SOCIAL   BETTERMENT  123 

substantial  revenue.  Notwithstanding  this  radical  change  in 
the  customs  tariff,  the  revenue  from  this  source  remained 
fairly  uniform  during  most  of  the  period,  but  with  a  marked 
tendency  to  increase  during  and  following  the  period  of 
the  Boer  War,  The  income  from  the  excise  taxes  steadily 
increased  during  the  century.  The  remaining  important 
sources  of  revenue  were  the  income  and  property  tax,  the 
estate  duties,  and  the  stamp  taxes.  The  income  tax  was 
discontinued  at  the  close  of  the  French  Wars  to  be  reimposed 
in  1842  and  has  been  of  growing  importance  ever  since, 
finally  becoming  the  most  important  source  of  tax  revenue 
in  the  financing  of  the  recent  war. 

Character  of  Expenditure 

Turning  now  to  the  purposes  for  which  the  money  of  the 
State  was  expended  during  this  century  we  face  a  situation 
of  great  interest. 

First  of  all  we  find  that  the  expenditure  for  the  payment 
of  the  interest  upon  the  debt  in  the  fiscal  year  ended  31st 
March,  1914,  was  £18,700,000,  a  reduction  of  £14,200,000 
from  the  year  1817  when  the  maximum  charge  was  reached. 

Military  and  Naval  Expenditure 

In  the  next  place,  we  discover  that  the  military  expendi- 
ture steadily  grew  during  the  entire  period.  The  Crimean 
War  cost  £73  million,  or  at  the  rate  of  over  £24  million  a 
year  for  the  three  years  (1854-1857)  affected  by  the  financing 
of  that  war  ;  but,  eliminating  this  special  feature,  we  find 
the  cost  of  the  military  establishment  in  time  of  peace  steadily 
mounting,  until  in  the  four  years  preceding  the  Boer  War 
it  averaged  over  £40  million  ;  more  than  the  average  military 
expense  during  the  Great  French  War,  although  some  £5 
inillion  less  than  during  the  most  expensive  period  of  that 
war.  The  Boer  War  cost  £281  million,  bringing  the  entire 
military  expense  for  the  period  (1899-1903)  up  to  £431  million, 
over  £100  million  a  year.  However,  for  the  peace  period  of 
over  ten  years  following  that  war  the  military  burden  averaged 


124 


ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 


annually  over  50  per  cent,  higher  than  it  had  averaged  in  the 
four  3'ears  preceding  the  war.  In  the  fiscal  year  ended  31st 
March,  1914,  the  military  establishment  cost  over  £11  million. 

Civil  Government  Expenditure 

Let  us  see,  now,  what  the  statistics  of  the  cost  of  civil 
government  show,  eliminating  after  1870  expenditures  for 
postal  services,  because  these  were  offset  by  a  corresponding 
or  greater  income.  We  find  that  the  record  can  be  allocated 
roughly  to  three  periods.  Down  to  the  time  of  the  Crimean 
War  (1854-1856)  these  expenditures  called  on  the  average  for 
about  ;^9  million  a  year,  increasing  during  the  last  decade 
to  about  £10  million.  They  then  reached  a  new  level, 
ranging  from  an  average  of  about  £12,500,000  during  the 
period  of  the  war  to  an  average  of  slightly  under  £23  million 
during  the  five  years  of  Gladstone's  administration  ending  in 
1874. 

Thereafter  they  mounted  rapidly  until  in  1914  they  had 
reached  over  £75  million  or  substantially  the  same  as  the 
military  expenditure.  They  had  run  neck  and  neck  with  the 
military  expenditure  for  the  previous  six  years. 

The  following  table  will  visualize  this  last  statement — 

CIVIL  GOVERNMENT  v.  MILITARY  EXPENDITURE. 


In  Millions  Sterling. 


Years  Ended 
31st  March. 
1909 
1910 
1911 
1912 
1913 
1914 
*  Postal  expenses  eliminated. 


Civil  1 

Military 

£ 

£ 

49,7 

59,0 

55,7 

63,0 

60,9 

67,8 

67,4 

70,5 

70,1 

72,4 

75,2 

77,2 

The  explanation  of  this  steady  increase  in  the  cost  of  civil 
government  is  to  be  found  in  the  awakening  of  the  civic  con- 
science to  the  duty  of  the  State  to  its  citizens.  As  we  have 
already  noted,  in  1839  Parliament  for  the  first  time  voted  a 
small  sum  for  public  education.     By  1854  the  expenditure  for 


PEACE  AND   SOCIAL   BETTERMENT  125 

this  purpose  reached  £559,000 — twenty  years  later  it  was 
more  than  four  times  as  great.  In  another  twenty  years  the 
expenditure  for  this  purpose  had  again  quadrupled,  while  in 
1914  it  was  over  £19  million,  twice  the  1895  amount.  To 
complete  the  record  we  may  note  that  this  sum  had  again 
doubled  in  the  year  ended  31st  March,  1920,  and  that  the 
budget  figure  for  the  current  year  (1920-1921)  is  £56  million. 
The  introduction  of  old  age  pensions  in  1908,  and  of  health 
insurance  in  1911,  added  another  similar  amount  to  the 
annual  expenditure  by  1913-1914,  and  these  expenditures 
tend  to  increase  in  almost  a  spectacular  way.  For  example, 
in  1919,  with  scarcely  a  word  of  objection,  old  age  pensions 
were  increased  by  Parliament  by  an  estimated  annual  sum 
of  about  £10  million,  bringing  up  the  estimated  future  annual 
expenditure  for  this  purpose  to  about  £28  million. 

The  table  on  the  next  page,  giving  the  distribution  of  the 
civil  government  expenditure  at  the  end  of  historical  periods 
from  1833  to  1914  inclusive,  offers  further  interesting 
data. 

Therefore,  to  sum  up,  we  find  that  the  striking  facts  con- 
nected with  public  finance  in  the  history  of  the  century  lying 
between  the  two  great  wars  were  these  :  A  revision  of  the 
tariff  and  revenue  laws  to  promote  freedom  of  trade  and  to 
provide  the  means  for  great  social  reforms  and  a  steady 
increase  in  military  expenses,  even  during  a  prolonged  period 
of  an  almost  complete  absence  of  war. 

Debt — Refunding 

Since  1817  several  refunding  operations  have  been  carried 
through.  The  most  important  of  these  operations,  and  the 
only  one  to  result  in  a  saving  commensurate  with  the  effort, 
was  that  made  by  Mr.  Goschen  in  1888  and  1889,  when  some 
£565  million  3  per  cents,  of  various  issues  were  refunded 
into  2 J  per  cent,  consols  at  a  saving  of  £1,411,000  a  year.  In 
accordance  with  the  terms  of  issue  the  interest  rate  on  these 
consols  became  2|  per  cent,  after  1903.  These  are  the  consols 
of  to-day.     Mr.   Gladstone  had  previously  endeavoured,  in 


Q 

(fi 

O 

w 

oi 

« 
o 

H 

►J 

>-i 

Q 

u 

^ 

« 

W 

H 

00 

Hh 

(/] 

!*: 

X 

w 

"S 

Ui 

■•i' 

^^ 

In 

(^ 

H 

o 

<o 

CO 

o 

s 
§ 

00 

8 

•-1 

> 

t-4 

o 

O 

o 

1-1 

W 

> 

t— 1 

u 

O 

ic-*-*        eo^^Da>r-oo 
oo"  a> '-"        id"  in  oi  cc  co  oi' 

»-i           -<  (N  "*  C5  r^  O) 

^j    4) 
en    O 

1    1    1         00  r*  t-N  00  CO  CO 
1     1     1          o"  (N '^'' co"  ■*  ■* 

Local 
Pur- 
poses 
and 
Capital 
Expen- 
diture 

III           1  ^.t^.c^.woo 
III           1  r>*  CD  ■><•"  tx"  CO 

Col- 
lecting 
Rev- 
enue 

OC  r>._  CO            00_  CO_  t>.  CD  O  ITi 
CO"  CO*  ■"I""           Tf"  C^"  CN  C^"  CO"  •*" 

Non-Ef- 
fective, 
Chari- 
table 
and 
Miscel- 
laneous 

COOiOO            00C0(NO05« 

r-^  O"  O"              O"  O"  -h"  ^  O"  '-" 

Old  Age 
Pen- 
sions 
and 
Insur- 
ance 

III     1 1 1 1 1  § 

Colonial 

and 
Foreign 
Services 

>/5-*CO            i/5CDCDtxCOi/2 

O*  O"  O"          O"  O"  O"  O"  CO*  ^" 

Educa- 
tion, 
Science 
and 

Art 

1  ©"o"        .-Tc^-ic  ojeo'aT 

Law 
and 

Justice 

C0__  00_  -^_           05_  C0_  C-J_  CD_  00_  i« 
O"  O"  — <"           C^"  ^f  cd"  CO"  CO*  ■*" 

Salaries 
and  Ex- 
penses 
Public 
Depart- 
ment 

i/5tx—            iCOll'OiCCO 
O'  O"  ^"           ^  r-T  of  (N  (m'  rf 

Public 
Works 

and 
Build- 
ings 

co_  <M_  oo_        oo_  --  r«._  tx_  CO  CO 

O"  o"  O"           O"  •-<''  rt"  i-T  c<f  co" 

Con- 
soli- 
dated 
Fund 
Services* 

OOti/5            XCDCDCOCD^ 

Fiscal 
Year 

Ended 

ccoo)-^      rti^i'^Dioeo-t 
rt9:J15    ■ScDt-.cooiO.-^ 

,_,0O  QOOO      ^'  Oj  rX/  <Xi  X)  Oi  (Ti 
'C                        CO 

8  " 

^§ 

^o 

6jOO 

■5  ■= 
>•-<  CD 

<U  --" 
^^ 
-^^^ 

og' 

CO  3 

(U  15 
en   cd 

D  O 
(3  -M 

O   3 

(X,> 

to  to 

.  (3 

6^ 

^"^^  ^  z 

■^  a  u  o  >> 

t3   4^   J<  ^-  b 

•»;    ct  i^H  "    •-< 
1)  "^    O  ^  "y 

5|S|og, 
^  b  +j  "S  "5 


O    (D 


PEACE  AND   SOCIAL   BETTERMENT  127 

1853,  to  effect  a  somewhat  similar  operation  but  the  conditions 
at  the  time  were  unfavourable  to  the  success  of  the  under- 
taking. An  operation  undertaken  in  1884  was  likewise 
unsatisfactory  in  its  final  outcome,  as  it  resulted  in  a  saving 
of  only  ;^46,756  a  year  on  some  £22,362,000. 

Some  Comparisons 

On  5th  January,  1817,  the  debt  stood  at  £850  million.  The 
fixed  charge  for  interest  and  management  at  that  time  was 
about  £32  million.  In  this  amount  was  included  the  sum  of 
about  £2  million  annuity  payments.  It  has  for  many  years 
been  customary  for  Treasury  officials  in  making  statements 
of  the  debt  to  capitalize  the  annuity  payments.  This  hardly 
seems  a  proper  method  for  1817  as  the  annuities  being  paid  at 
that  period  were  really  bonuses,  or  additional  interest,  and 
represented  no  expenditure  of  capital.  However,  if  to  agree 
with  the  Exchequer  method  of  to-day  we  roughly  calculate  the 
capital  value  of  the  annuities  outstanding  in  1817  at  fifteen 
years  purchase,  or,  say,  £30  million,  this  would  bring  up  the 
par  value  of  the  debt  in  1817  to  £880  million,  equivalent  to 
about  £52  per  head  of  population. 

In  1817  the  national  wealth  was  estimated  to  be  £2,700 
million,  about  £159  per  capita.  Therefore  the  national  debt 
at  that  time  was  almost  one  third  of  the  national  wealth. 
In  1914  the  national  wealth  was  estimated  at  £14,500  million, 
say,  £315  per  capita.  The  debt,  which  was  then  £711  million, 
was  thus  less  than  5  per  cent,  of  the  wealth.  The  fixed 
charge  at  the  earlier  date  was  8  per  cent,  of  the  estimated 
national  income  of  £400  milhon,  while  at  the  later  date  it  was 
only  a  trifle  over  1  per  cent,  of  the  estimated  national  income 
of  £2,250  million.  Therefore  the  growth  in  population,  in 
wealth  and  in  earning  power  had  made  the  burdensome  debt 
of  1817  a  very  unimportant  affair  by  1914, 

Again,  the  expenditures  of  the  Government  for  all 
purposes  amounted  in  1817  to  £71  million,  about  18  per 
cent,  of  the  national  income  ;  in  1914  the  expenditures 
of  the  Government    had    risen    to   £212    million   but   this 


128 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


amount  was  not  quite  9J  per  cent,  of  the  estimated  national 
income. 

Casting  these  figures  into  tabular  form  we  arrive  at  the 
following  statement.  It  should  be  borne  in  mind  that 
national  income  is  the  estimated  income  of  the  British  people 
as  a  whole,  not  the  revenue  of  the  Exchequer.  This  latter 
would  be  substantially  the  same  as  the  Government 
expenditure. 

THE  FISCAL  CHANGES  OF  A  CENTURY. 
Grand  Totals,  Expressed  in  Millions. 
Italics  indicate  decreases. 


Date 

Popl. 

Natl. 
Wealth 

Debt 

Debt 
Charge 

Natl. 
Income 

Gov't. 
Expend. 

Jan.  1817    . 
Aug.  1914   . 

17 
46 

2,700 
14,500 

850 
711 

32 
24 

400 
2,250 

71 
212 

Changes  . 

29 

11,800 

139 

8 

1.850 

141 

Stated  Per  Capita  and  Percentage. 


Date. 

Natl. 
Wealth 

Debt 

Natl. 
In- 
come 

Debt 
Charges 

Gov't. 
Expenditure 

Per 
Cap. 

Per 
Cap. 

0/ 

/o 
Wealth 

Per 
Cap. 

Per 
Cap. 

0/ 

Income 

Per 
Cap. 

% 
Nat'l. 
Income 

Jan.  1817 
Aug.  1914 

£ 

159 
315 

£ 
50 
15 

31-5 
4-9 

£    s. 

23  11 

49     - 

£  s. 

1   17 
0  10 

8-00 
106 

£  s. 

4     4 
4     7 

18-0 
9-4 

Changes 

156 

35 

26-6 

25     9 

1     7 

6-94 

3 

8-6 

In  words  of  Sir  Stafford  H.  Northcotc,  writing  in  1862,  the 
great  advance  of  the  British  nation  from  1817  to  1914  may  be 
summed  up  as  due  "  to  the  progress  of  science,  and  its  appli- 
cation to  all  the  arts  of  life,  the  development  of  the  railway 
system,  the  improvements  in  agriculture  and  manufactures, 
the  discoveries  of  gold  and  the  impulse  given  to  colonization." 


PEACE  ^ND   SOCIAL  BETTERMENT  129 

To  these  general  causes  he  added  the  great  improvement 
which  had  taken  place  in  the  fiscal  administration.  Since  the 
time  when  he  wrote  has  come  the  age  of  electricity  with  the 
wonderful  impulse  which  it  has  given  to  the  arts  and  sciences, 
especially  as  applied  to  the  material  well-being  of  the  nation  ; 
the  tremendous  advance  in  transportation  methods,  on  land 
and  sea  and  now  in  the  air  ;  the  intensive  methods  of  produc- 
tion ;  improvements  in  finance  and,  as  an  impressive  result 
of  the  recent  war,  the  welding  together  of  the  constituent 
political  units  of  which  the  Empire  is  composed  into  a  unified 
whole,  one  nation  in  sentiment  and  purpose  composed  of 
many  separate  political  units. 

The  history  of  public  finance  in  England  during  the  crucial 
period  of  the  World  War  has  already  been  related. 


9— (1823) 


CHAPTER  XXIII 

THE  ANCIENT  EXCHEQUER 

There  is  every  evidence  that  the  early  kings  had  in  use 
well  developed  methods  of  adniinistering  their  finances. 

The  Exchequer 

The  Exchequer  was  the  place  where  the  King's  revenue 
was  received,  where  it  was  kept,  supervised  and  controlled, 
and  from  whence  it  was  issued.  There  were  three  officers  of 
the  Exchequer,  each  of  whom  had  control  over  the  issue  of 
the  money.  The  money  was  kept  in  chests,  each  chest  having 
three  locks  and  each  of  these  officers  having  his  key  to  one  of 
the  locks.  One  of  these  officers  called  the  Teller,  was  the 
cashier  who  received  the  money  ;  then  there  was  the  Clerk  of 
the  Pells,  who  recorded  on  a  pell  or  parchment  all  receipts 
and  issues  ;  finally  there  was  the  Auditor,  who  examined  the 
records  and  whose  duty  it  was  to  see  that  no  money  was 
issued  except  in  accordance  with  the  law,  and  with  the 
sanction  of  Parliament. 

This  system  existed  until  well  into  the  nineteenth  century, 
although  certain  changes  were  of  course  made  in  respect  to 
the  actual  custody  of  the  cash.  In  1834  the  whole  system 
for  the  administration  of  the  public  finances  was  revised 
and  modernized. 

The  Accounting 

The  King's  revenues  were  collected  by  the  Sheriffs  and  by 
them  were  twice  a  year,  at  Easter  and  at  Michaelmas  (the 
day  after  the  feast  of  St.  Michael,  about  the  end  of  September), 
paid  to  the  King's  treasury. 

On  the  appointed  day  the  Sheriffs  would  bring  their 
accounts  and  the  money  which  they  had  collected  to  the  hall 
in  which  the  settlements  were  to  be  made,  known  as  the 

130 


THE  ANCIENT  EXCHEQUER  131 

Receipt  of  the  Exchequer.  Upon  entering  the  hall  the  Sheriff 
would  see  at  the  farther  end  a  table,  about  ten  feet  in  length 
and  five  in  breadth,  covered  with  a  black  cloth  which  was 
divided  by  white  lines  into  squares  about  a  handbreadth  in 
width.  It  was  this  chequered  cloth  which  gave  name  at  once 
to  the  system  of  accounting  and  to  the  place  of  meeting  and 
which  persists  to  this  day  as  the  designation  of  the  English 
Treasury. 

Seated  on  a  bench  to  the  right  of  the  table,  clothed  in  their 
scarlet  robes,  the  Sheriff  would  see  the  Bishop,  the  Justiciar 
who  represented  the  King,  and  the  Chancellor  of  the  Excheq- 
uer ;  also  the  Constable  and  several  Chamberlains  or  courtiers. 
Seated  at  the  far  side  of  the  table  were  the  Treasurer  and 
the  scribes  or  clerks.  Facing  them  were  the  calculator 
and  the  cutter  of  tallies.  Seated  on  benches  arranged  around 
the  room  were  the  taxpayers,  watching  to  see  that  the  accounts 
as  they  affected  their  interests  were  correctly  stated.  The 
Sheriff  upon  approaching  the  table  would  place  on  it  his 
receipt  tallies  and  the  silver  coins  for  use  in  settling  his 
account.  He  would  then  take  his  place  at  the  foot  of  the 
table  facing  the  Chancellor  and  other  dignitaries.  The 
game  of  chess  which  was  to  decide  his  indebtedness  then 
proceeded. 

In  the  early  days  only  the  priests  and  monks  were  able  to 
read  and  write  ;  therefore  the  accounting  had  to  be  visualized. 
To  serve  as  counters  foreign  coins  were  used.  The  calculator 
would  place  the  coins  in  the  proper  spaces  on  the  chequered 
cloth  to  represent  the  Sheriff's  indebtedness.  Below  he  would 
place  the  silver  paid  in  by  the  Sheriff  and  counters  representing 
any  credits  due  to  him.  Thus  was  visualized  the  state  of 
the  account,  and  the  adjustments  required  to  effect  a  settle- 
ment could  be  readily  determined.  The  Chancellor's  scribes 
meanwhile  had  entered  a  statement  of  the  account  in  duplicate 
on  the  rolls  of  vellum  which  were  used  in  place  of  the  paper 
account  books  of  to-day.  A  tally — ^receipt — ^prepared  by 
the  tally  cutter  would  be  given  to  the  Sheriff  to  be  carefully 
preserved  until  the  next  settlement. 


132  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

Tallies 

These  tallies  were  sticks  of  some  hard  wood  on  one  side  of 
which  notches  were  cut  of  peculiar  shapes  and  sizes  corres- 
ponding to  the  figiires  of  account  which  they  represented.  The 
stick  was  bored  near  one  end  so  that  it  could  be  filed  upon  a 
rod.  When  the  sums  paid  had  been  cut  on  the  two  edges  of 
the  stick,  and  the  name  had  been  recorded,  it  was  split  nearly 
to  the  bottom,  so  that  one  part  contained  a  stump  or  handle 
while  the  other  was  only  a  flat  strip.  The  larger  part  or  tally 
was  retained  by  the  Sheriff,  while  the  smaller  part  remained 
in  the  Treasury.  This  was  known  as  the  counter-tally  or 
counter-foil.  As  it  was  customary  for  the  Sheriff  to  make 
only  a  partial  settlement  at  Easter,  it  was  necessary  for  him 
to  bring  with  him  at  Michaelmas  his  Easter  tallies  in  order 
that  he  might  obtain  the  necessary  credits  in  making  his 
settlement  for  the  year.  The  validity  of  the  tallies  presented 
could  be  determined  by  comparing  them  with  the  counter- 
foil. The  use  of  tallies  at  the  Exchequer  was  not  finally 
discontinued  until  1834.  On  the  10th  of  October  of  that  year 
we  read  in  the  Gentleman's  Magazine  that  the  most  ancient 
revenue  department  in  the  State,  the  Receipt  of  the  Exchequer, 
terminated  ;  also  that  on  the  16th  the  tallies  were  burned, 
and  on  the  same  day  the  Houses  of  Parliament  were  destroyed 
by  fire.  The  presumption  was  that  the  flues  were  overheated 
on  account  of  the  great  fire  caused  by  the  burning  tallies. 

The  use  of  tallies  has  left  a  permanent  imprint  upon  the 
English  language  and  usages.  The  larger  part  of  the  tally  was 
sometimes  called  the  stock  and  the  smaller  part  the  foil. 
Down  to  about  a  hundred  years  ago,  if  one  lent  money  to  the 
Bank  of  England  or  to  the  Exchequer,  tallies  were  cut  for  the 
amount  ;  the  bank  kept  the  foil  and  the  creditor  received  the 
stock.  He  thus  held  "  bank  stock  "  or  "  Exchequer  stock  " 
of  the  amount  recorded  upon  the  tally.  Wlien  the  form  of 
cheque  was  adopted  it  is  true  that  it  was  not  called  a  foil,  but 
the  part  retained  by  the  payer  was  called  the  counter-foil, 
and  the  word  "  cheque  "  itself  goes  back  ultimately  to  the 
same  root  as    "  Exchequer." 


THE   ANCIENT  EXCHEQUER  133 

The  Ancient  Treasury 

The  taxes  in  the  early  days  were  frequently  paid  in  kind, 
as  well  as  in  money.  The  wealth  of  the  King  and  of  his  nobles, 
not  in  the  form  of  landed  property,  forests,  flocks,  herds  and 
the  like  was  represented  not  alone  by  money  but  by  gold  and 
silver  plate,  by  jewels  and  gems  and  by  richly  embroidered 
robes.  Such  articles  belonging  to  the  King  were  kept  in  his 
Treasury.  For  a  long  time,  wherever  the  King  went  the 
Treasury  also  went.  The  principal  treasuries  ultimately  came 
to  be  located  at  Winchester  and  at  Westminster,  and  finally 
with  the  growing  importance  of  London  the  Treasury  was 
definitely  located  there. 

It  would  be  interesting  to  consider  here  the  methods  of 
administering  the  Treasury  in  the  early  days  and  the  duties 
of  the  officials.  However,  it  is  impossible  to  do  this  in  the 
space  at  our  disposal.  Therefore  we  will  proceed  at  once  to 
an  examination  of  the  system  now  in  use. 


CHAPTER  XXIV 

THE  MODERN   FISCAL   SYSTEM 

The  finances  of  Great  Britain  are  conducted  on  what  is 
known  as  the  budgetary  plan.  Briefly  stated,  this  plan 
involves  the  preparation  by  the  executive  of  a  "  definite  plan 
or  proposal  for  financing  the  business  of  a  future  period  both 
with  respect  to  revenues  and  expenditures." 

The  Budget 

The  policy  of  the  English  budget  is  settled  by  the  Chancellor 
of  the  Exchequer  and  the  details  worked  out  by  the  permanent 
staff  of  the  Treasury.  The  budget  is  presented  by  the 
Chancellor  to  the  Commons  usually  in  April  or  May.  Some- 
times a  supplementary  budget  is  presented  in  the  Autumn. 
Previous  to  the  presentation  of  the  budget  a  financial  state- 
ment containing  carefully  prepared  estimates  of  revenue 
and  expenditure  is  placed  in  the  hands  of  each  member  of 
Parliament.  These  estimates  are  compared  with  the  actual 
expenditure  for  the  past  year,  also  with  the  estimates  for  that 
year.  At  the  time  of  presentation  the  Chancellor  explains, — 
usually  in  great  detail — the  reason  for  the  proposed  methods 
of  taxation  or  borrowing  to  be  followed  in  obtaining  the 
revenues  necessary  with  which  to  meet  the  expenditures. 
Many  of  the  budget  speeches  have  been  notable  for  their 
lucidity  and  interest.  Gladstone's  budget  speeches  were 
among  his  greatest  efforts.  Parliament  can  approve  or  reject 
the  recommendations  of  the  budget  but  does  not  add  to  its 
items  or  make  an  appropriation  in  excess  of  the  amount 
proposed. 

Certain  appropriations  are  of  a  continuing  or  permanent 
character,  such  as  those  for  the  support  of  the  King  and  his 
household  ;  the  interest  and  management  of  the  public  debt, 
and  the  salaries  for  the  higher  judicial  officers.      These  are 

184 


THE   MODERN   FISCAL  SYSTEM  135 

designated  as  "  Consolidated  Fund  Services."  Annual  appro- 
priations for  the  other  public  expenses  are  known  as  the 
"  Supply  Services."  Appropriations  for  such  services  cannot 
be  made  "  unless  recommended  from  the  Crown."  That  is, 
unless  set  forth  in  the  budget.  This  puts  an  effective  check 
on  log-roDing  and  trading  and  upon  ill-considered  expendi- 
tures. So  carefully  are  the  estimates  of  expenditures  and 
receipts  made  that  in  normal  times  the  actual  results  vary  but 
slightly   therefrom. 

The  Public  Tresisury 

The  Treasury  Department  controls  all  financial  operations 
of  the  Government  which  in  any  manner  affect  the  amount 
of  funds  that  Parliament  will  be  called  upon  to  vote  for  their 
support  or  the  expenditure  of  funds  when  granted.  Though 
termed  a  department  the  Treasury  is  technically  a  board. 
Prior  to  1714  the  head  of  the  department  was  known  as  the 
Lord  High  Treasurer.  In  that  year  the  office  was  put  in 
commission  ;  that  is,  while  the  office  remained  a  single  one 
provision  was  made  that  its  duties  should  be  performed  by  a 
board  consisting  of  a  First  Lord  of  the  Treasury,  the  Chancellor 
of  the  Exchequer,  and  three  Junior  Lords.  Though  this 
board  has  continued  in  existence  until  the  present  time  all 
real  authority  has  in  fact  passed  from  its  hands  into  those  of 
the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer. 

The  political  heads  of  the  Treasury  are  the  First  Lord 
(practically  always  the  Prime  Minister),  the  Chancellor  of  the 
Exchequer,  a  Parliamentary  Secretary,  a  Financial  Secretary, 
and  three,  or  sometimes  four,  Junior  Lords,  the  fourth  Junior 
Lord  not  being  a  paid  official.  The  First  Lord  does  not 
concern  himself  with  the  actual  management  of  the  affairs 
of  the  department  of  which  he  is  nominally  the  chief  officer. 
He  has  the  patronage  of  the  board,  save  in  so  far  as  he  dele- 
gates it  in  minor  matters  to  the  ParUamentary  Secretary, 
and  nominates  for  approval  by  the  Sovereign  the  incumbents 
of  certain  Crown  livings.  He  also  recommends  to  the  Sover- 
eign the  names  of  persons  to  be  the  recipients  of  civil  Ust 


136  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

pensions  or  royal  bounty.  The  three  (or  four)  Junior  Lords 
have  certain  minor  duties  in  connection  with  the  Treasury, 
but  their  real  duties  consist  in  acting  as  assistants  to  the 
ParUamentary  Secretary  of  the  Treasury,  who  acts  as  the 
chief  whip  of  the  Government  in  the  House  of  Commons. 
Thus  the  officers  nominally  in  charge  of  the  Treasury  in  fact 
pay  little  or  no  attention  to  the  direction  of  the  affairs  of 
that  department,  but  concern  themselves  almost  entirely 
with  parUamentary  matters.  A  Treasury  Minute  often 
concludes  with  the  words  "  My  Lords  approve,"  and  the 
Junior  Lords  affix  their  names  formally  to  innumerable 
documents  which  they  are  not  expected  to  peruse  and  for 
which  they  take  no  responsibility  whatever. 

The  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  and  his  Aids. 

The  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  is  the  real  responsible 
head  of  the  Treasury.  It  is  his  function  to  regulate  the  pubUc 
income  and  expenditure,  to  propose  any  change  of  taxation 
or  any  measures  affecting  the  public  debt,  to  keep  the  pubhc 
services  in  funds  and  to  supervise  the  currency  and  the 
banking  legislation  of  the  country.  He  is  ex  o-fficio  Master 
of  the  Mint.  He  is  assisted  on  the  administrative  side  by  the 
Financial  Secretary.  The  Financial  Secretary  attends  to 
the  details  of  financial  business  and  in  particular  to  the 
sanction  of  estimates  and  to  seeing  them  through  the  House 
of  Commons.  The  Financial  Secretary  also  represents  in  the 
House  of  Commons  a  number  of  departments  which  have  no 
ministerial  head.  Both  the  Patronage  Secretary  and  the 
Financial  Secretary  leave  office  whenever  a  change  of 
administration  takes  place. 

The  foregoing  are  political  officers  with  seats  in  Parliament. 
At  the  head  of  the  permanent  staff  of  the  Treasury  there  is 
a  Permanent  Secretary,  and  under  him  are  three  Controllers, 
with  the  status  of  heads  of  departments.  Each,  subject  to 
the  general  supervision  of  the  Permanent  Secretary,  is  directly 
responsible  to  the  Board  (that  is  to  say,  in  practice,  to  the 
Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer)  for  one  of  the  main  departments 


THE   MODERN   FISCAL   SYSTEM  137 

of  the  work  of  the  Treasury,  namely  Finance,  Supply  Services, 
and  Establishment.  By  Supply  Services  is  meant  voted 
Expenditure,  while  Estabhshments  include  all  questions  of 
personnel,  salaries,  wages,  the  staffing  of  public  departments, 
pensions,  and  kindred  matters.  Each  of  the  three  depart- 
ments is  organized  in  several  divisions,  with  an  Assistant 
Secretary  at  the  head  of  each,  with  three  or  four  subordinates. 

The  Consolidated  Fund 

In  1787  Parliament  provided  that  there  would  be  one 
general  fund  into  which  all  the  revenues  of  the  Crown  should 
be  put  and  from  which  all  disbursements  should  be  made. 
Prior  to  this  time  it  had  been  customary  to  allocate  certain 
definite  charges  against  each  of  the  principal  sources  of 
revenue.  It  is  stated  that  in  1785  there  were  no  fewer  than 
seventy-four  charges,  involving  seventy-four  separate  accounts, 
imposed  upon  the  customs  revenue,  while  the  militia  charges 
were  defrayed  from  the  land  tax  and  certain  hereditary 
annuities  were  met  out  of  the  post  office  revenues.  To  correct 
this  situation  the  "  Consolidated  Fund  Act  "  was  passed. 
A  similar  Act  was  passed  in  1816  in  reference  to  revenues 
and  expenditures  of  Ireland  and  the  two  consolidated  funds 
were  further  consolidated  into  one  consolidated  fund  for 
Great  Britain  and  Ireland.  The  Consolidated  Fund  stands 
to  the  credit  of  the  Exchequer. 

The  Bank  of  England  and  the  Treasury 

The  custodians  of  this  account  are  the  Bank  of  England 
and  the  Bank  of  Ireland.  Thus  these  banks  are  substituted 
for  the  "  strong  box,"  or  chest,  of  the  old  Exchequer  for  the 
keeping  of  the  public  treasure.  The  duty  of  the  banks  is 
confined  to  receiving  the  public  revenue  and  paying  it  out  to 
officers  who  are  charged  with  the  actual  responsibility  of 
settling  and  paying  public  obligations.  These  officers  take 
the  place  of  the  Teller  under  the  old  cashbox  system. 

The  centralization  of  all  public  payments  in  London  and 


138  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

the  direct  hold  of  the  Bank  on  the  process  of  payment  lend  an 
importance  to  the  central  organization  of  public  financial 
administration  in  England  such  as  it  possesses  in  no  other 
country.  Through  the  medium  of  the  Bank  public  revenues, 
without  being  collected  in  provincial  treasuries,  are  trans- 
mitted direct  by  the  Receivers  of  Taxes  to  London,  after  local 
expenses  have  been  met.  The  Bank  of  England  thus  actually 
receives  the  surplus  cash  of  all  the  revenue  departments. 
The  greater  part  of  the  Government  expenditures  is  paid  in 
London  itself.  Expenditures  which  have  to  be  met  outside 
of  London  and  which  cannot  be  paid  by  the  receivers  from 
their  collections  are  always  remitted  from  London.  This 
keeps  the  management  of  the  money  in  the  hands  of  the 
central  authorities. 

Each  of  the  head  offices  concerned  with  the  administration 
of  the  various  branches  of  the  revenue  has  an  account  at 
the  Bank.  All  the  money  received  by  these  offices  is  in  the 
first  instance  credited  to  one  of  these  accounts.  Only  mis- 
cellaneous receipts  which  are  managed  by  the  Treasury  are 
paid  direct  to  the  Exchequer  account. 

Revenues  received  by  the  collectors  in  the  provinces  are 
remitted  to  London  by  means  of  bills  of  exchange  which  are 
made  out  to  the  head  office  to  which  payment  is  to  be  made. 
Should  there  be  a  branch  of  the  Bank  of  England  in  the 
neighbourhood  of  the  collector  he  deposits  his  money  there, 
and  the  amount  is  at  once  credited  to  the  general  account  of 
the  Commissioners  of  Inland  Revenue  in  the  books  of  the 
Bank,  but  as  the  Bank  has  only  eight  ^  branches  remittances 
are  more  usual.  The  bills  run  for  two  or  three  days  and 
are  sent  to  the  Bank  by  the  Commissioners  of  Inland 
Revenue  to  be  cashed.  When  they  have  been  honoured  the 
Bank  credits  the  account  of  the  office  with  the  amount  in 
question. 

The  Bank  of  Ireland  acts  for  account  of  the  Exchequer  in 
Ireland,  while  in  Scotland  the  six  principal  banks  act  in  turn 
in  this  capacity,  as  agent  for  the  Bank  of  England. 

^  In  the  provinces. 


THE  MODERN   FISCAL  SYSTEM  139 

The  Government  account  has  been  kept  by  the  Bank  of 
England  since  1834  under  the  name  of  "  The  Account  of  His 
Majesty's  Exchequer."  Into  this  account  all  the  public 
revenues  are  paid  as  soon  as  possible  after  their  collection 
and  from  it  all  disbursements  are  made.  The  Exchequer 
account  is  not  the  account  of  a  distinct  central  treasury  as 
opposed  to  various  other  treasuries.  It  is  the  repository  for 
all  public  moneys. 

The  Pajrmaster  General 

The  English  system  of  disbursing  public  funds  rests  upon 
the  principle  of  having  a  single  Paymaster  General  for  the 
whole  Government.  He  receives  the  money  from  the 
Exchequer  that  is  required  for  the  payment  of  public  obli- 
gations and  makes  such  payments  himself  or  advances  money 
to  "  sub-accountants  "  for  that  purpose.  "  Sub-accountants  " 
are  defined  by  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Departments  Act  as 
"  those  who  receive  advances  by  way  of  imprests  from  prin- 
cipal accountants  or  who  receive  fees  or  other  public  moneys 
through  other  channels."  The  Paymaster  General  is  in  no 
sense  an  accounting  officer.  He  has  nothing  to  do  with  the 
examination  and  settlement  of  claims.  His  sole  function  is 
that  of  making  payment  of  orders  drawn  upon  him  by 
accounting  officers  proper.  His  responsibility  is  limited  to 
that  of  satisfying  himself  that  the  orders  for  payment  are  in 
due  form  and  are  supported  by  the  proper  documents  as 
required  by  law. 

Originally  there  were  a  number  of  paymasters,  one  for  the 
army,  one  for  the  navy  and  a  number  for  the  several  civil 
services.  During  the  years  1830-1856  these  were  abohshed 
and  their  duties  consolidated  in  the  single  office  of  Paymaster 
General.  A  special  feature  of  this  system  is  that  although 
the  Paymaster  General  keeps  a  separate  account  in  respect 
to  each  vote  for  the  civil  services  and  a  separate  consolidated 
account  with  each  of  the  departments  of  the  army  and  navy, 
he  keeps  but  one  general  balance  from  which  he  makes  pay- 
ments on  account  of  all  the  votes.     This  means  that  so  long 


140  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

as  he  has  a  suf&cient  balance  he  can  pay  any  order  drawn 
upon  him,  regardless  of  the  vote  to  which  it  relates,  whether 
he  has  requisitioned  sufficient  funds  on  account  of  that  vote 
or  not,  provided  that  the  aggregate  of  the  vote  for  the  year 
is  not  exceeded.  Any  payment  on  account  of  a  vote  in  excess 
of  a  sum  requisitioned  for  that  vote  is  subsequently  adjusted 
by  a  future  requisition. 

Accounting  Officers 

As  we  have  seen,  the  duty  of  the  Paymaster  General  is 
that  of  paying  obligations  found  to  be  due.  It  is  for  the 
accounting  officers  to  determine  what  payments  are  so  due 
and  payable.  Technically  an  accounting  officer  is  the  officer 
charged  with  the  duty  and  responsibility  for  the  expenditure 
of  a  vote  and  of  rendering  an  account  of  the  manner  in  which 
the  duty  is  performed. 

An  accounting  officer  is  designated  for  each  vote. 
Theoretically  there  might  be  as  many  accounting  officers  as 
there  are  votes.  The  same  person  is  usually  made  the  accounting 
officer  for  all  the  votes  for  a  department  or  other  important 
branch  of  the  public  service.  The  duty  of  rendering  an 
account  of  the  manner  in  which  funds  are  expended  is  a  part 
only  of  the  duties  of  this  officer.  He  is  also  charged  with  the 
supervision  and  control  of  all  the  financial  operations  of  the 
department  to  which  he  is  attached.  He  is  the  officer  whose 
approval  is  required  before  any  expenditure  of  funds  can  be 
made  or  liability  entered  into.  The  accounting  officer  has 
entire  charge  of  the  financial  operations  of  his  service.  He 
is  responsible  for  all  expenditures  and  the  rendition  of  the 
accounts.  His  duties  pertain  not  only  to  the  settling  of 
accounts  but  to  the  incurring  of  obligations  in  the  first 
instance.  He  has  the  duty  of  seeing  not  only  that  the  law  is 
strictly  complied  with  but  that  all  expenditures  are  made  to 
the  best  possible  advantage.  In  a  word  he  is  the  watch  dog 
of  his  service  and  the  permanent  financial  secretary  of  his 
department. 

There  is  a  complete  and  thorough  system  of  audit. 


THE  MODERN   FISCAL  SYSTEM  141 

Financial  Reports 

Various  financial  reports  are  submitted  annually  to  Par- 
liament. The  principal  report,  known  as  Finance  Accounts, 
dates  from  1802  and  has  not  changed  its  essential  character 
since  its  first  issue.  The  accounts  are  made  up  for  the  fiscal 
year  which  terminates  on  31st  March,  and  are  laid  before 
Parliament  on  or  before  30th  June  of  each  year.  Finance 
Accounts  also  contains  a  statement  in  considerable  detail  in 
regard  to  the  national  debt. 

Note. — The  principal  dependence  for  the  statements  made  in  this 
chapter  has  been  placed  upon  a  report  on  The  System  of  Financial 
Administration  of  Great  Britain,  made  in  1917  to  the  Institute  for 
Government  Research,  by  Professors  William  F.  Willoughby,  Westel  W. 
Willoughby,  and  Samuel  McCune  Lindsay,  and  upon  the  History  of 
the  Bank  of  England  and  Its  Financial  Services  to  the  State,  by  Eugene 
Von  Philippovich.  We  are  also  indebted  to  English  friends  for  valued 
information  in  regard  to  recent  changes  in  procedure. 

The  word  "  vote  "  which  frequently  occurs  in  the  chapter  is  used  in 
a  sense  equivalent  to  our  term  "  appropriation,"  while  the  word 
"  issue  "  is  equivalent  in  our  usage  to  "  pay." 


CHAPTER  XXV 

CONCLUDING  THOUGHT  AND  DEDUCTIONS 

We  have  now  traced  the  history  of  English  pubHc 
finance  from  the  time  of  the  accession  of  William  III  down 
to  the  present  day.  We  have  found  that  with  relatively 
unimportant  exceptions  the  debt  has  arisen  from  the  extra- 
ordinary expenses  of  the  various  wars  in  which  the  nation 
has  been  engaged.  We  have  seen  that  the  cost  of  war  has 
progressively  increased  and  that  after  each  war  all  expenses 
of  the  State  have  risen  to  a  new  level.  We  have  found  little 
disposition  to  reduce  debt  during  the  intervals  of  peace. 
However,  we  have  found  that  the  growth  of  the  nation  in 
material  resources  has  reduced  in  each  historical  period  the 
burden  of  the  debt. 

We  have  learned  that  the  English  financiers  have  always 
derived  a  substantial  portion  of  the  cost  of  each  war  period 
from  taxation.  Turning  to  the  revenue  from  taxation,  we 
discover  that  the  most  flexible  source  of  taxation  has  proved 
to  be  the  income  tax.  The  finance  ministers  since  that  form  of 
taxation  was  introduced,  have  found  it  comparatively  easy  to 
meet  the  requirements  of  a  new  situation  by  slightly  or  largely 
raising  or  lowering  the  rate  of  this  tax.  It  is  no  longer  neces- 
sary to  hunt  up  fantastic  sources  of  income,  such  as  taxation 
of  bachelors,  hearth  taxes,  window  taxes  and  the  like.  Again, 
so  far  as  the  customs  are  concerned,  it  has  been  learned  that 
much  better  results  can  be  obtained  from  a  moderate  tax 
on  a  few  articles  of  common  use  than  by  taxing  many  articles. 
This  simplifies  administration  and  reduces  the  cost  of  collecting 
the  taxes. 

As  to  the  purposes  for  which  national  taxes  are  raised,  we 
find  that  outside  of  the  cost  of  wars,  the  maintenance  of  the 
military  establishment  in  times  of  peace  and  the  public  debt 
burden,  other  expenses  are  relatively  small.  Therefore,  if  a 
way  could  be  discovered  to  end  wars  and  to  pay  off  the  debt, 

142 


°  o 

<  :^ 


o   q 


S5  o 

CD  J 

c  < 

W  § 

^  2 

a  w 

W  Ph 

X  s 


O  -S 

<! 


X  ^ 


&°°^ 
^    a 


Cash 

BegiQ- 

ning 

of 

1 

-■2 

2.B' 

as 

H   4) 

p< 

TO    >    W 


o.  ><T3  a 

£  «  "•  Si 


sa 


1r 


:><w 


0.g 
^  to 

t;.a 

t!  <^ 


r^*" i~>"rs*V"oo"«"erro"pi"Vin"irroo to  r^V "flaoo od o't-^'S H iC  t 
-■^  „„coc^t>.oo<ou535toaot>.ooSft5oS?)Se 


oo  «  »  e^_r»  N  •*  «o  CO  CO  «  r»_oo  oi_>o  oo  «d  »  »  os  o  o  «  ih  w  oo  * 


w  ^00  CO  00 1/5^-^r^— *_»ftcD  00  w  u5  ^«  ^e^-^  x-^cocoootHtooo 

^H       t-i  ^^  cl  ^^  C£>  CO  i/i  lyj  U5  1/5  r^  CD  t^  00  03  i3>  05  «  O  CO  to 

.-lOSC^  cooi 


W  ^  C*5  CO  00  OS  CO  O  iH 

I  to"  I    I  efVo'rCiorrcoas 
I        II  C02     C4as 


■-<_co_oo_co_oo  i/5_o_co_~  ifl  co_— co_M_c^_eo  — _05_-*  00  o_o  eo  o_e*co  o_o 

c^"  co"  CO  «"  >n  t^  t~-"  o -^  10  00  oT  oT  —  m"  30"  05"  ^r  <K  co"  —  oT  •<r  —  00  00  oi' 01 

_«_i_eocoi«ir>u3ior»cDr»ao»CT>cooCT!cot? 

—  i-i  —  coo 


Tl'CO  N^'*  CO  CO  t^t-^05_rN  05_r>  C0_C^_U5  ■*  !>•  CO  CO  —  C0C0C0M^'*OO 

o"  cT  cT  cT  o  o  cT  o  o"  o  o —"  c^"  o  o"  •-«"——' c^" -^  1/5* -^  04*  crT  ©i" -^  co"  u3 


—  --"OJCO  •*  rH 


1/5"—  1    I  i/5'ir5"co"i/5"io"o5'ioi/5'odiorro5"r» 

-•11  —  —-<  CO  W  •>»•■.»•  Sj 


—  — "— .J'^f— c^"— Nco  Vt-C'io'V-*  co"co"co^fc^ci^^'^^'lHco"•*«' 

o  1-4 


I    I    I 


eoeJ_iON  00  Neo_r» —  •>«•_•*  ift  CO  i«r>^N  1-4  o_o  © 
I  ©.-"t-rco'co't-CprrCtCt-ros''©'— —  iooo"ooo'eo"io 


1 1 1 1  1 1 1  1 1 1 1 1 1 1  1 1 1 1 1 1  i  I  «"IS5Si 


■"•C*'--"  — —  —  MMMC^NCOMC0COO» 


o  r^  CD  CO  ■*  co_QO_in  00 10 —  0505  "fl  "fi  c^_<n  w  coco  cooo  —  coco  m  o_o 
—  o  —  •-<'— "—"  — "cTcTV■>r"o5''--''oo''co''^^'^fco'co"o"a5''cn"o"■*''celoo5"e9 

—  — MCSC^NC^M  — —  MCOOJCOfO* 

«     -9 


oot>-"'*o>03io<oi'5>/3oiMt^coMr^'*r~t~'<'Oco>nco^Ti"OQ 
0005  0  — co-vmcDt^oooso  — co-w*in>ricot-.ooooo5  0.H  — c^« 
cocor^t^r^t^t^i^r^r^r^ooooooooooooooQDooooooooo5ao505A 


133 


o  B  <-' 

«  3  <« 


2^ 

H    4> 

»   9 


IS 


.Q 


CO  — 


2'^ 


H   u 
ri  S 


144  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

the  people  of  Great  Britain  thereafter  need  scarcely  feel  the 
burden  of  taxation  for  other  purposes,  that  is,  unless  it 
seemed  wise  to  undertake  enlarged  plans  for  social  better- 
ment. As  to  such  undertakings,  we  have  found  that  since 
the  widening  of  the  suffrage  there  has  been  a  growing  ten- 
dency toward  social  betterment  through  State  co-operation, 
and  that  when  the  war  broke  over  the  world  in  1914  there 
were  then  pending  plans  which  would  have  involved  further 
heavy  expenditures  for  such  purposes,  and  that  notwith- 
standing the  heavy  financial  burdens  of  the  war  there  has  been 
during  the  war  period  an  increasing  expenditure  for  education, 
for  old  age  pensions,  and  for  similar  purposes. 

From  the  point  of  view  of  the  investor,  especially  of  the 
foreign  investor,  we  find  that  since  the  Revolution  of  1688 
England  has  scrupulously  kept  her  engagements  with  the 
public  creditor,  that  she  has  done  so  in  times  of  stress  and  that 
her  burdens  to-day,  while  heavy,  are  not  much  heavier,  in 
proportion  to  national  wealth  and  income,  than  those  which 
she  has  borne  at  times  in  the  past.  Recent  statistics  of  her 
commerce  show  that  the  country,  even  in  the  unsettled  year 
1919,  has  quietly  been  forging  ahead  again.  While  we  expect 
to  vie  with  her  in  a  generous  rivalry  for  business,  we  cannot 
but  be  cognizant  of  the  fact  that  her  long  experience  in  the 
shipping  trade,  extending  over  the  centuries  from  the  time  of 
Drake's  famous  voyages  in  the  days  of  Queen  Elizabeth,  give 
her  a  peculiar  advantage  in  this  line.  The  experience  of  her 
bankers  and  manufacturers  is  an  asset  of  incalculable  value. 
Her  loyal  overseas  citizens,  the  peoples  of  her  self-governing 
Dominions,  Crown  Colonies  and  Dependencies  are  a  bulwark 
of  strength  and  afford  a  wonderful  home  market,  which  it  will 
be  surprising  not  to  see  specially  developed  hereafter. 

What  England  requires  to-day  to  insure  her  material  well- 
being  is  a  heavy  output  of  goods  and  services  which  the  world 
will  take  in  exchange  for  the  food  which  she  must  buy  in  order 
to  maintain  her  population  and  for  the  raw  materials  of 
manufacture,  most  of  which  she  must  seek  without  her  own 
borders. 


(x 

o" 

s 

Z 

o 

1 

,—  I/) 

ir> 

O     5 

*-H 

c^    « 

a> 

(J)    < 

'«— ^ 

<^  ^ 

Pi 

to  ^ 

s 

— '  •< 

rt  S 

Q 
OS 

o 

w  ^ 

W   Q 

(:^ 

bo 

ffi  2 

0 

•S 

C)    « 

V) 

!< 

a 

< 

(/) 

>H 

s 

C     0! 

CO 
X 

fa    w 


H    E 


wJ       ^       ^ 

"   ?   s 


X 


(K 

^ 

o 

Oi 

(A 

a 

rf) 

< 

00 

M 

CD 

>^ 

(■J 

(A 

M 
PS 

o 

5 

i-i 

H 

U 

Z 

H 

Pi 

C) 

o 

fa 

-♦• 

10— (1823) 


S3. 


Q"-' 


U5ii5e<r»©t^^e««»-     e^r^eoM'-o     or^«toeoe<»n     o<d 


••oooooo     or> 


•3  ."S 


S  ^5  o  2 
o«     >< 


ID  o  O) -- o>  w ■*      t*N 


o>cO'*NO?oo>     lO'n 


»i-i»F->c4r4     ^inmcnmcA     e^Ne^oe^  — »-      '^r* 


©■*«  r»«Oif* --o»^e<_o 


^  ^ -^ -^  t^  t^  C*5  C^  ■*  CO        O  i/S  00  •«r  C^  O 
ifiOOt^OOXOO 


-J-  o  —  o  e^  o)  a  I 
xaOr~.t>.r^'^t^   't^o 


00  ^f*  rC'^t'oo  CO  CO  o  c^~ 


-H       — ^coc^       t-»  00  lO  "ft  CD  CO 


ooco_t~co_co__tc  ■*»o>_'**    S 
oot^oooi  oioo  us  — r^tji   «, 

—  <NOS(MCDOj[  _a 


'^  «J  c 


Qfl 


3  >> 


.::  o  c  V 


o  3i  i> 


CCt^>ft<ftiftCO       t>>  CC  X  00  3>  0>  O 


—  o  CO  —  r>._co  00  lO  ift  o_o> 
fo  00  rr  t?"  5?"  g-"  o"  ^  —  to  CO 


NOJC^  CD  ©1       M    BO 


1*1111 


000>'*NNCe'-W^0005      -^eo  CO  COlft  00      '".ffl'*'*'\1*©«o_c> 
,-rt~rco''cD"ift'e4"t>.''oO'ft'"cc'     ift  —  O'rift'ift     cD"t-rco"'**N"-*  o"^— "to'f^ 
i,      S  — c^—      CD  t^  ift  >ft  in  ift     t^cD  t^oooovogiocDc 


NOc^oooi^t^i^c^co      O)  05  CO  r^  CO—     ^■"1'^'^^'^^.^''^^^ 
"— "— CO  c^'co  c^'^'^oToT     oi'c^ao  (jToo  00     oo  co  cd  x  co  tft  r^  t>  "^  c^  iH 

—  C01N(NC^C^I        NC^MMNlNM^NCOg 


^N  COO 
lO       COO 


09 


O  O  »ft  O  W  ift  "^  CD  Oi^OO  CD_      CD  — OOC^^CO^ 

^cD  — 'c^Tc^odco  ^co  ■^"•ft"     r^odco  ift  cd'co"      -    .   ,  _  _    —  ,  .    — 

—  Vi,— .c~,t^v*,^j-,-     -^  j,3c^  —  —  —  —        eOMN(NMCOOellt^-riO 

—  lO       — lO 
^      —06 


cDor^c>io  — ooxxo     Oi  co  ift -^co  ■'i^     ^^^'^^^"^1^'^^ 
o'o'o'— '—  —  —"— —  —  n"     t^o'oooJ'o'—     co"ift'"iftorfi'co"eo''eoarooo 

oe     — 1> 


oor^  —  •^OiOiiftcD'ftiftc^  Oc^p^coc^t^-^  or^r^-^ocDiftco^d^-^oo 
QOa>o  —  co-^tftcor^XCTii^.o- co-^-^ift  ^iftCDr^xx05Or-i  —  ojci 
cDCDr^r^r^r^r^r>r^r^r^^xxxxxx^xxxxxx05O505aiO5 


•s-2  -S^f-t"; 


32 


d 

K 

s 

« 

An 

r.xi 

Lj 

F 

3 

c 

< 

i" 

O 

146  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

If  class  distinctions  are  forgotten  in  a  general  effort  for  the 
common  welfare — in  short,  if  the  Golden  Rule  of  doing  as  you 
would  be  done  by  is  made  the  rule  of  action  for  conservatives 
and  liberals,  for  labour  and  for  capital,  there  need  be  no  fear 
but  that  England  will  maintain  a  strong  and  wholesome 
national  life,  that  prosperity  and  happiness  will  be  hers  and  that 
the  wonderful  credit  standing  which  she  has  enjoyed  for  many 
generations  will  be  maintained  and  strengthened  in  coming 
years. 

The  tables  printed  on  pages  143  and  145  summarize  the 
statistical  data  for  the  entire  period  from  1688  to  1920. 
They  have  been  compiled  with  great  care  and  will  be  found 
worthy  of  study. 


The  Bank  of  England 


CHAPTER  I 

A   BANKING  EVOLUTION 

The  Bank  of  England  is  more  than  a  corporation.  It  is  a 
personality.  The  first  of  the  modern  banks,  if  a  bank  two 
and  a  quarter  centuries  old  may  be  so  called,  it  is  also  the 
most  powerful.  This  standing  does  not  come  because  of 
its  resources,  for  even  its  large  capital  and  surplus  of 
£17,800,000  are  exceeded  or  closely  approached  by  those  of 
several  of  the  London  joint -stock  banks,  which  also  have 
greater  total  resources.  The  Federal  Reserve  Banks  of  the 
United  States  have  combined  capitals  and  surpluses  nearly 
double  those  of  the  Bank  of  England,  and  gold  holdings 
nearly  five  times  as  large.  Nevertheless  the  Bank  of  England 
has  a  prestige  and  a  standing  which  is  all  its  own,  won  by  years 
of  honourable  and  capable  administration  of  the  finances  of 
the  world's  greatest  money  capital. 

The  Functions  of  the  Bank 

The  Bank  of  England  while  privately  owned  performs  all 
the  functions  of  a  State  bank.  It  also  conducts  a  general 
banking  business,  receiving  the  deposit  accounts  of  corpora- 
tions and  of  individuals. 

From  1844  until  1914  it  possessed  practically  the  sole 
right  of  note  issue  in  England,  but  the  Treasury,  or  Currency, 
notes  now  in  circulation  greatly  exceed  the  combined  circu- 
lation of  the  Bank  of  England  and  of  the  Scotch  and  Irish 
banks. 

The  functions  of  the  Bank  in  connection  with  the  Exchequer 
described  in  another  chapter  are  of  great  importance. 

The  prerogative  of  the  Bank,  which  has  accrued  to  it  by  a 
process  of  evolution,  of  holding  the  ultimate  reserve  for  the 

147 


148  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

banking  and  commercial  interests  of  the  United  Kingdom  is, 
in  normal  times,  what  gives  the  Bank  its  premier  position 
among  English  financial  institutions.  The  other  distinctive 
purpose  which  it  serves,  especially  in  times  of  national 
stress,  is  by  the  alchemy  of  credit  to  liquefy  the  assets  of 
the  Kingdom  and  put  them  to  work  for  its  preservation  and 
advancement. 

Holds  Ultimate  Banking  Reserves  of  Nation 

As  to  the  first  of  these  functions,  that  of  holding  the 
ultimate  banking  reserve  of  the  Kingdom,  it  has  come  to  be 
an  axiom  of  the  Englishman's  financial  creed  that  as  the 
Government  is  back  of  the  Bank  it  cannot  fail.  Therefore,  it 
is  argued,  there  is  no  reason  why  the  other  banks  should 
carry  any  important  reserve  other  than  their  deposit  with  the 
Bank,  although  some  of  the  joint-stock  banks  in  recent  years 
have  adopted  the  policy  of  carrying  a  substantial  amount  of 
gold  in  their  own  vaults.  The  amount  so  held  in  July,  1918, 
was  estimated  by  the  "  Committee  on  Ciirrency  and  Foreign 
Exchanges  after  the  War,"  of  which  Lord  Cunliffe  was 
Chairman,  at  £40  million.  The  Scotch  and  Irish  banks,  as 
explained  in  the  previous  chapter,  also  carry  cash  balances 
which  may  include  a  certain  amount  of  specie.  Except  as  to 
the  gold  so  held,  the  banking  business  of  Great  Britain,  with 
its  world-wide  ramifications,  depends  upon  the  strength  of 
the  Bank  and  the  wisdom  of  the  management,  and  in  con- 
sequence the  commercial  credits  of  the  world  also  may  be 
said  to  rest  largely  on  the  same  foundation.  At  least,  such 
was  the  case  until  1st  August,  1914.  The  raising  of  the  Bank's 
rate  usually  would  automatically  turn  the  exchanges  in  favour 
of  London.  The  lowering  of  the  rate  would  make  for  "  easy 
money  "  throughout  the  world.  Not  only  so,  but  the  volume 
of  the  business  which  could  be  done,  even  in  remote  parts  of 
the  world,  was  determined  by  the  attitude  of  the  Bank.  This 
delicate  credit  structure  with  its  world-wide  relations  is  now 
partly  dislocated  as  a  result  of  the  war  and  will  not  properly 
function  again  until  England  returns  to  a  specie  basis. 


A  BANKING  EVOLUTION  149 

Mobilizes  National  Credit  Resources 

The  other  special  function  served  by  the  Bank  is  that  of 
mobilizing  the  financial  resources  of  the  people  for  great 
financial  and  commercial  emergencies  and  especially  for 
meeting  the  needs  of  the  Government  in  time  of  war.  This 
is  accomplished  because  of  the  fact  that  the  ultimate  banking 
reserve  of  the  nation  carried  with  the  Bank  can  be  made  the 
basis,  on  occasion,  for  a  great  expansion  of  credit.  It  is  the 
modern  development  of  our  forefathers'  idea  of  a  "  fund  of 
credit."  The  reserve  of  the  joint-stock  and  private  banks 
deposited  with  the  Bank  has  come  to  be  considered  a  basis 
for  an  extension  of  credits  to  their  borrowing  customers. 
As  a  result  of  long  experience,  it  is  found  that  a  given  reserve 
is  sufficient  to  warrant  the  granting  of  credits  for  several 
times  its  amount.  This  principle  is  well  known  to  bankers 
and  constantly  observed  in  their  transactions. 


CHAPTER   II 

THE   GENESIS  OF   BANKING 

It  will  be  of  interest,  before  taking  up  the  history  of  the 
Bank  of  England  and  discussing  its  functions  more  in  detail, 
briefly  to  consider  the  evolutionary  process  which  led  up  to 
conditions  making  this  bank  a  possibility. 

Banking  Originated  in  Italy 

The  enterprise  of  the  medieval  Italian  merchants  carried 
them  to  all  parts  of  the  known  world.  It  was  natural,  there- 
fore, that  the  Popes  should  commission  them  to  collect  their 
revenues  and  to  transport  them  to  Rome.  As  these  revenues 
were  paid  in  the  moneys  of  the  countries  where  collected,  the 
merchants  readily  became  money  changers  and  early  origi- 
nated and  used  letters  of  credit  and  bills  of  exchange.  It 
was  in  keeping  with  their  other  activities  to  act  as  collectors 
and  farmers  of  the  revenues  of  the  sovereigns  of  the  countries 
which  they  visited.  As  farmers  of  the  revenues  they  would 
make  advances  to  the  King  and  reimburse  themselves,  with 
a  profit,  by  collecting  the  customs  or  some  other  branch  of 
the  King's  revenue,  which  was  given  to  them  in  "  ferme  " — 
that  is,  as  secmity.  From  such  advances  against  the  revenues 
it  was  an  easy  step  to  making  direct  loans.  Sometimes  the 
repayment  of  these  loans  was  guaranteed  by  the  pledge  of 
the  Crown  jewels,  the  royal  wardrobe,  or  the  very  diadem 
itself.  As  the  payment  of  interest  ("  usury  ")  was  forbidden 
by  the  Church,  the  merchants  were  rewarded  for  these 
advances  in  various  indirect  ways.  Sometimes  the  King 
agreed  to  buy  jewels  or  other  wares.  Sometimes  he  granted 
trading  concessions,  or  used  his  influence  in  behalf  of  the 
merchants  with  other  potentates.  Sometimes  he  made 
the  merchants  a  substantial  cash  present  for  the  use  of 
the  money  beyond  the  time  originally  agreed  upon  for  its 
repayment. 

150 


THE   GENESIS  OF  BANKING  151 

The  necessities  for  ready  money  by  those  taking  part  in 
the  crusades  gave  the  ItaHans  special  opportunities  for 
making  gain  from  conversions  of  properties  of  various  kinds 
into  liquid  funds. 

The  Italian  Bankers  and  the  Plantagenet  Kings  of  England 

The  Plantagenet  kings  of  England  from  the  time  of  Henry 
II  through  the  reign  of  Edward  III — that  is,  over  a  period  of 
more  than  two  hundred  years,  from  the  middle  of  the  twelfth 
centiiry  to  well  into  the  fourteenth  century — were  active 
patrons  of  the  Italian  merchant  bankers.  The  archives  of  Old 
England  contain  copies  of  contracts  between  the  Crown  and 
the  merchants  dating  from  as  far  back  as  the  reign  of  King 
John.  Following  is  a  translation  from  the  Latin  of  such  a 
contract,  which  must  have  been  entered  into  during  1199,  the 
first  year  of  John's  reign.  It  refers  to  the  payment  of  a  debt 
incurred  by  Richard  I,  presumably  in  connection  with  his 
crusade.  Note  in  the  last  paragraph  the  promise  of  the  King, 
"  by  way  of  thanks  for  your  generous  waiting  .  .  .  your 
waiting  shall  not  seem  burdensome  to  you." 

DEBENTURE  OF  THE  REIGN  OF  JOHN. 

John,  by  the  grace  of  God  King,  etc.  ...  to  his  beloved  friends 
Speren,  Barageton  and  their  associate  merchants  of  Placentia  {i.e. 
Piacenza),  greeting. 

Know  that  we  wish  to  pay  to  you  two  thousand  marks  and  125 
marks,  which,  for  love  of  the  dear  memory  of  King  Richard,  our 
brother  and  in  accordance  with  his  own  request  you  lent  to  William 
Andegavensis  {i.e.  of  Anjou)  and  R.  Bangorensis,  bishops,  and  to 
Stephen  Ridel,  for  carrying  out  the  business  of  our  dearest  grandson, 
the  illustrious  King  Otho ;  in  the  Senate  of  Rome.  And  therefore, 
by  these  presents,  we  bind  ourselves  to  you  for  such  an  amount, 
promising  that  on  the  next  Feast  of  St.  Michael  after  our  coronation, 
at  our  exchequer  in  England,  we  shall  cause  to  be  paid  to  you,  or  to  your 
known  envoy,  upon  his  bringing  and  presenting  these  presents,  625 
marks,  and  at  the  Easter  next  following  500  marks  in  the  same  place, 
and  at  the  following  Feast  of  St.  Michael  500  marks  at  the  same  place 
and  likewise  500  marks  at  the  next  following  Easter  we  shall  cause 
to  be  paid  at  our  exchequer  in  England  to  you  or  to  your  known  envoy 
upon  presentation  of  this  our  note  of  indebtedness.  And  nevertheless 
by  way  of  thanks  for  your  generous  waiting  we  shall  reply  to  you, 
the  Lord  favouring,  that  your  waiting  shall  not  seem  burdensome  to 
you.     Witness  my  hand  at  Rothomagum,  the  25th  day  of  August. 

(1199  A.D.) 


152  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

Following  is  a  letter  of  credit  dating  from  the  second  year 
of  the  same  reign.     This  also  is  translated  from  the  Latin. 

LETTER  OF  CREDIT  OF  THE  REIGN  OF  JOHN 

John,  by  the  Grace  of  God  ....  to  all  merchants,  etc.  Know 
all  of  your  body,  that  we  do  appoint  the  bearers  of  these  presents, 
Hugo  of  Feritas  and  Robert  of  Sablenc,  to  prosecute  our  business  at 
the  Senate  of  Rome,  and  to  merchants  from  whom  they  shall  have 
borrowed  money  up  to  500  marks  silver,  for  prosecuting  this  business, 
we  shall  be  held  bound  to  pay  the  money  in  full.  And  by  these 
presents  we  are  constitute  principal  debtors  for  this  amount  and, 
the  term  agreed  upon,  in  accordance  with  the  convention  made  between 
our  aforenamed  clerks  and  the  merchants.  To  those  who  shall  bring 
these  presents  to  us  or  to  our  mandatory  along  with  letters  from  the 
aforenamed  clerks  showing  the  sum  of  money  borrowed  from  the 
protestants  we  shall  cause  the  money  to  be  paid  in  full.  Witness  my 
hand  at  Fissa,  the  6th  day  of  January.     (1201  a.d.) 

The  transactions  with  the  Italians  ended  disastrously  for 
them  and  disgracefully  for  Edward  III,  when,  because  of  his 
failure  to  meet  his  obligations  to  them,  the  great  Florentine 
houses,  known  as  the  Bardi  and  the  Peruzzi,  were  unable  to 
meet  their  commercial  engagements,  and  finally  became 
bankrupt. 

The  King's  Factor 

Dating  from  the  reign  of  Edward  III  we  find  the  kings  of 
England  having  dealings  with  English  merchants.  The  king's 
factor  (financial  agent — banker)  held  an  honourable  position 
at  court.  He  was  charged  with  the  arduous  duty  of  keeping 
the  king's  coffers  filled.  One  of  the  first  merchants  to  hold 
this  position  was  William  de  la  Pole,  of  Hull,  who  in  1338 
and  1339  lent  Edward  III  what  for  those  times  were  immense 
sums  of  money.  He  not  only  freely  supplied  the  King  from 
his  own  resources,  but,  in  order  to  secure  additional  sums 
from  others,  he  even  mortgaged  his  own  real  estate.  He  is 
styled  in  all  public  instruments  "  our  faithful  and  well  beloved 
merchant,"  Passing  by  others  worthy  of  mention,  we  find, 
about  two  hundred  years  later.  Sir  Thomas  Gresham  acting  as 
royal  agent  or  factor  for  Edward  VI  and  later  for  each  of  his 
sisters,  Queen  Mary  and  Queen  Elizabeth.  Just  as  De  la  Pole 
arranged  loans  at  Antwerp  for  Edward  III,  so  two  centuries 


THE   GENESIS  OF   BANKING  153 

later  we  find  Gresham  doing  for  Edward,  Mary  and  Eliza- 
beth. Thus  it  would  appear  that  after  the  downfall  of  the 
Italian  merchants,  De  la  Pole  was  able  to  win  the  confidence 
of  a  group  of  Flemish  merchants  and  that  on  the  whole  their 
transactions  had  proven  to  be  sufficiently  satisfactory  to 
cause  them  and  their  successors  to  be  wdling  to  continue 
financial  relations  over  two  centuries — relations  which  were 
to  continue  for  yet  other  centuries. 

Early  Italian  Corporate  Banks 

Before  we  take  up  the  consideration  of  the  development  of 
banking  in  England  let  us  now  retrace  our  steps  and  see  what 
happened  in  Italy  following  the  commercial  crisis  due  to  the 
failure  of  the  Bardi  and  Peruzzi.  It  would  appear  that  there 
were  recurrent  revivals  of  business  activities  and  of  failures 
not  unlike  the  recurring  crises  with  which  we  have  become 
familiar  in  modern  times.  Notwithstanding  occasional  dis- 
asters the  banks,  as  they  came  to  be  called  as  early  as  1421, 
grew  and  multiplied.  They  were  banks  both  of  deposit  and 
discount.  "  Giro  "  payments — that  is,  payments  by  means 
of  transfers  on  the  bankers'  books — were  made  from  the  early 
part  of  the  fifteenth  century.  Transferable  certificates  of 
deposit  were  issued  and  used  "  hke  coin."  So  these  early 
banks  were  banks  of  issue  as  weU  as  banks  of  deposit.  Some 
of  these  private  banks  became  very  powerful.  However, 
recurrent  failures  which  sometimes  were  due  to  bad  banking 
practices,  but  often  to  forced  loans  to  the  Government  which 
tied  up  a  large  part  of  the  bankers'  resources  in  a  fixed  form, 
weakened  confidence  in  the  private  bankers  and  led  to  the 
establishment  in  Venice,  in  1584,  of  the  first  public  bank. 
This  was  known  as  the  Banco  della  Piazza  del  Rialto.  This 
bank  restricted  itself  to  keeping  depositors'  money  in  security, 
and  to  paying  it  out  or  transferring  it  according  to  their 
directions. 

In  1587  the  private  banks  were  suppressed.  The  need  for 
further  banking  facilities  led  in  1619  to  the  establishment  of 
the  famous  Banco  del  Giro,  which  in  1637  absorbed  the  Banco 


154  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 

della  Piazza  del  Rialto.  The  Banco  del  Giro,  or,  as  it  came  to 
be  known,  the  Bank  of  Venice,  continued  in  business  until 
1806. 

Another  famous  early  Italian  bank  was  an  outgrowth  of 
the  business  of  the  Compania,  or  Casa,  di  San  Giorgio  of 
Genoa.  This  institution  is  described  by  Andr6ades  in  his 
History  of  the  Bank  of  England  as  an  association  of  State 
creditors  who  managed  the  revenues  of  the  republic,  owned 
colonies  and  possessions,  maintained  armies  and  fleets,  made 
war  and  concluded  treaties,  and  combined  with  all  these 
various  functions  the  duties  of  a  bank  of  deposit.  Its  genesis 
dates  back  to  the  organization  in  1148  of  a  company  to 
make  a  loan  to  the  republic.  By  1250  a  number  of  such  com- 
panies, which  were  called  "  Compere,"  were  merged  under  the 
name  of  Compera  del  Capitalo.  In  1407  Jean  le  Maingre, 
Marshal  of  France,  changed  this  compera  into  the  Ufficio  di 
San  Giorgio,  which  continued  until  1736  the  business  of 
making  advances  to  the  State.  It  soon  became  a  State 
within  the  State,  possessing  great  power  and  influence.  Just 
how  early  it  began  to  do  a  banking  business  is  not  evident.  Its 
cartulary  or  registered  notes  were  somewhat  similar  in 
character  to  modern  bank  notes.  They  were  certificates  of 
deposit,  but  as  the  deposits  were  not  held  as  a  definite  fund  to 
secure  them  but  used  in  the  general  business  of  the  bank  the 
notes  in  fact  circulated  on  the  general  credit  of  the  bank. 
This  bank  continued  in  business  until  1797  when  it  failed. 
So  much  for  the  early  Italian  banks. 

The  Bank  of  Amsterdam 

In  the  Bank  of  Amsterdam,  founded  1608  or  1609,  the 
Dutch  possessed  the  third  public  bank  to  be  organized. 
Founded  after  the  Italian  banks,  it  continued  in  business  until 
1790,  when  its  affairs  were  liquidated  by  the  city,  which 
guaranteed  its  solvency.  The  Bank  of  Amsterdam  theo- 
retically held  in  trust  the  actual  coin  or  bullion  deposited  with 
it,  issuing  its  notes  against  such  deposits.  At  a  time  when  the 
coinages  were  systematically  sweated  and  clipped  the  function 


THE  GENESIS  OF  BANKING  155 

which  this  bank  performed  of  practically  insuring  the  integ- 
rity of  the  currency  was  a  valuable  one  to  the  commercial 
community.  Thus  its  notes  came  to  command  a  premium 
for  purposes  of  exchange.  The  failure  of  the  bank  was 
precipitated  by  the  disclosure  that  its  assets  had  been 
clandestinely  loaned  to  the  Dutch  East  India  Company. 
To  return  to  England. 

The  English  Goldsmith  Bankers 

Those  who  first  engaged  in  business  operations  in  England 
analogous  to  the  modern  profession  of  banking  were  the 
Italian  merchants  commonly  known  as  Lombards.  Hence 
Lombard  Street  in  London,  where  their  homes  and  places  of 
business  were  chiefly  situated.  Naturalized  foreigners  and 
finally  natives  took  up  the  business.  The  goldsmiths,  as 
they  were  called,  united  the  trades  of  the  goldsmith,  of  the 
dealer  in  bullion  and  of  the  money-lender.  In  the  latter 
capacity  the  goldsmith  also  conducted  a  pawn-brokerage 
business.  Sometimes  the  pawns  were  the  royal  jewels  and  the 
jewels  of  the  nobility,  for  the  goldsmith  was  a  canny  person 
and  usually  took  good  care  to  obtain  security  for  his  ad- 
vances. A  traveller  who  visited  England  from  the  Continent 
in  1593  tells  us  that  in  Lombard  Street  he  saw  "  all  sorts  of 
gold  and  silver  vessels  exposed  to  sale,  as  well  as  ancient  and 
modern  coins."  The  goldsmiths  gave  and  took  a  bond  on 
receiving  and  lending  money.  They  exacted  heavy  payments 
for  their  loans.  About  the  time  of  Charles  I — say,  from  1625 
— it  became  customary  for  the  merchants  to  entrust  their 
balances  to  the  goldsmiths.  Before  that,  for  some  time,  they 
had  been  in  the  habit  of  depositing  them  for  safe  keeping  in 
the  Tower  of  London.  However,  after  Charles  had  seized 
£130,000  temporarily  deposited  in  the  Tower  while  en  route 
from  Spain  to  Dunkirk,  the  merchants  were  afraid  to  make 
further  deposits,  even  though,  after  they  had  consented  to 
make  the  King  a  loan  of  £40,000,  he  had  released  this  particular 
deposit. 

They  then  got  into  the  habit  of  entrusting  their  surpluses 


156  ENGLISH  PUBLIC   FINANCE 

to  their  cashiers.  Some  of  these,  of  a  thrifty  turn  of  mind, 
instead  of  "  wrapping  their  talent  in  a  napkin  "  deposited 
the  trust  fund  with  the  goldsmiths  and  so  realized  interest 
which  substantially  increased  their  yearly  stipend  from  their 
employers.  The  latter  then  awoke  to  the  fact  that  by  such  an 
arrangement  their  funds  could  be  safe-guarded  and  income 
increased  and  so  deposited  them  directly  with  the  goldsmiths 
for  their  own  account. 

This  custom  developed  greatly  during  the  troublous  times 
of  the  civil  wars  and  in  the  Cromwcllian  era  until  it  is  said 
that  half  the  gold  in  the  kingdom  came  to  be  stowed  away 
in  the  goldsmiths'  vaults.  The  banking  business  of  the 
mercantile  community  was  in  the  goldsmiths'  hands  and  from 
this  business  they  derived  handsome  revenues,  laying  the 
foundations  for  fortunes,  some  of  which  have  continued  to 
the  present  day,  and  for  banking  businesses  which  in  one 
form  or  another  still  endure. 

Charles  II  dealt  the  goldsmiths  and  their  clients  a  cruel 
blow  when  in  1672  he  confiscated  the  loans  which  the  gold- 
smiths had  made  to  the  Exchequer.  This  "  Stop  of  the 
Exchequer,"  already  noted  in  a  previous  chapter,  involved 
the  large  sum  of  £1,328,526  and,  as  might  be  expected,  was 
followed  by  serious  consequences  to  the  goldsmiths  and  to  the 
entire  community. 


CHAPTER   III 

THE   pARLY  HISTORY  OF  THE   BANK  OF  ENGLAND 

Thus  it  was  when,  about  twenty  years  after  the  happening 
of  the  events  just  described,  WiUiam  Paterson  of  Dumfries 
came  forward  with  a  project  for  a  bank  which  would  be 
the  equal  in  strength  of  the  Banks  of  Amsterdam,  of 
Venice  and  of  Genoa,  he  received  a  ready  hearing  in  busi- 
ness circles.  In  1691  Paterson  urged  the  establishment  of  a 
national  bank,  so  as  to  provide  a  safe  means  of  borrowing 
money  at  proper  rates  of  interest.  Many  of  the  great  London 
merchants  supported  his  project,  notably,  Michael  Godfrey, 
one  of  the  richest  and  most  honest  city  men  of  that  time. 
The  plan  was  coldly  received  by  Parliament,  but  the  neces- 
sities of  the  Government  for  funds  with  which  to  prosecute 
the  war  against  France  led  a  committee  of  the  Commons, 
to  which  a  consideration  of  the  project  had  been  referred, 
to  advise  Paterson  that  they  would  receive  any  proposal  to 
advance  £1  million  on  a  perpetual  fund  of  interest.  As  the 
committee  were  unwilling  to  concede  any  reciprocal  rights, 
Paterson  and  his  friends  naturally  were  not  interested  and 
abandoned  the  project  for  the  time.  Finally  in  1694  they 
achieved  their  purpose,  but  the  proposal  "  had  to  be  smuggled 
into  Parliament  under  cover  of  a  bill  imposing  a  new  duty 
on  tonnage,  for  the  benefit  of  the  capitalists  lending  money 
toward  carrying  on  the  war  with  France."  This  was  known 
as  the  Tonnage  Act. 

As  it  finally  became  a  law  the  bill  provided  that  the  sub- 
scribers to  a  perpetual  loan  of  £1,200,000  should  form  a 
corporation  to  be  called  "  The  Governor  and  Company  of  the 
Bank  of  England."  The  fund  so  raised  was  to  be  loaned  to 
the  Government. 

The  First  Years  of  the  Bank 

When  the  Bank  of  England  was  organized  in  1694  it  com- 
bined all   the  methods  of  banking  then  known.     Its  capital 

157 


158  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

of  £1,200,000  was  loaned  wholly  to  the  State  for  an  annual 
return  of  £100,000 — that  is,  for  "  an  interest  "  of  8  per  cent, 
and  £4,000  for  management.  The  Bank  acquired  the  right 
to  receive  deposits,  to  issue  its  demand  notes  and  to  loan 
its  funds.  It  also  bought  and  sold  bills  of  exchange.  It 
was  organized  entirely  with  private  capital  and  as  a  private 
enterprise.  However,  it  had  very  close  relations  with  the 
State  from  the  day  of  its  organization.  At  first  it  had  no 
monopoly  rights  of  any  kind.  It  was  political  necessity  which 
brought  it  into  being.  The  Whig  Government  was  sorely 
in  need  of  funds  to  maintain  its  existence  against  foreign 
aggression,  unsettled  conditions  in  Ireland  and  a  latent  liking 
of  many  of  the  great  Tory  families  for  the  deposed  James  II, 
whom  they  would  have  been  pleased  to  have  seen  back  on  the 
throne.  The  Bank  not  only  provided  William  III,  sometimes 
called  Dutch  William,  and  his  Whig  supporters  with  the 
original  £1,200,000,  but  it  stabilized  the  exchanges,  helped  to 
market  the  long  annuities  with  which  the  people  were  just 
becoming  familiarized,  and  also,  even  in  those  early  days,  made 
temporary  advances  to  the  Government.  The  Bank  began 
business  without  a  dollar  of  cash  capital.  Its  resources  were 
the  "  fund  of  credit,"  as  the  saying  of  the  time  had  it,  due  to 
its  holdings  of  the  Government  debt,  its  note  issuing  rights 
and  its  deposits. 

The  good  effects  of  such  an  institution  were  immediately 
felt.  The  Exchequer  officials  no  longer  had  to  make 
"  frequent  processions  to  the  city  to  borrow  money  on  the  best 
and  nearest  public  seciirities,  at  10  or  12  per  cent,  per  annum 
interest,"  while  the  mercantile  community  had  a  source 
from  which  to  obtain  loans  at  reasonable  rates.  One  of  the 
earliest  and  most  important  of  the  public  functions  of  the 
Bank  was  to  assist  in  the  rehabilitation  of  the  coinage  which 
was  so  debased  at  the  time  of  William's  accession  that  one 
of  the  first  acts  of  the  new  government  had  been  to  arrange 
for  its  restoration. 

In  the  early  days  the  Bank  allowed  interest  on  its  notes 
and  also  upon  its  deposits,  a  practice  afterwards  abandoned. 


EARLY  HISTORY  OF  THE   BANK  OF  ENGLAND  159 

To-day  the  Bank  is  chiefly  a  bankers'  depository  and  therefore 
an  offer  to  pay  interest  upon  deposits  would  place  it  in  com- 
petition with  its  chief  patrons  and  interfere  with  its  functions 
as  the  holder  and  protector  of  the  ultimate  banking  reserve 
of  the  nation.  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  inception  of  its 
business  it  desired  to  build  up  its  deposits  and  increase  its 
note  issues  by  attracting  money  from  the  goldsmiths  ;  there- 
fore the  payment  of  interest  was  a  powerfiil  lever  for  this 
purpose.  The  Bank  was  nearly  wrecked  in  the  second  year  of 
its  career  by  its  goldsmith  enemies,  who,  taking  advantage  of 
the  fact  that  there  was  a  great  scarcity  of  coin  because  of  the 
restoration  of  the  coinage  then  in  progress,  gathered  up 
quantities  of  the  Bank's  notes  and  demanded  immediate 
redemption.  As  the  Bank  could  not  promptly  enough  secure 
coin  from  the  mint  it  could  not  respond  and  was  temporarily 
compelled  to  suspend  specie  payments.  To  ease  this  situation 
the  first  Exchequer  bills  were  issued. 

The  necessities  of  the  Government  led  from  time  to  time 
to  overtures  to  the  Bank  for  larger  advances.  Taking  advan- 
tage of  such  situations  the  Bank  made  them  the  basis  for 
securing  valuable  concessions  and  additional  privileges,  in 
particular  a  monopoly  of  note  issue.  Mutual  concessions  on 
the  part  of  Government  and  Bank  were  made,  until  to-day 
the  Bank  has  the  exclusive  right  of  note  issue  in  England, 
except  for  the  unimportant  exception  noted  on  page  167,  the 
management  of  the  debt  and  the  Government  deposit  accounts. 
The  ownership  and  control  of  the  Bank  remains  to  this  day 
in  the  hands  of  its  proprietors.  The  State  has  no  proprietary 
interest  in  the  capital  of  the  Bank  and  no  voice  in  its 
management. 

Instead  of  attempting  a  detailed  history  of  the  Bank  we 
may  to  better  advantage  consider  certain  special  happenings 
in  its  long  career. 

There  are  three  especially  notable  periods  in  this  history. 
These  are  the  twenty-three  years  of  the  Great  French  War, 
the  events  of  1844  and  the  connection  of  the  Bank  with  the 
financing  of  the  recent  war.  ^    The  notable  services  rendered 

1  Paxt  1,  Chapter  V.,  and  Chapter  VI.  • 


160  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

by  the  Bank  during  the  crucial  period  of  the  past  six  years 
have  already  been  discussed.  We  may  now  consider  the  two 
other  great  crises  in  its  history. 

Lessons  of  Eighteenth  Century — Commercial  Crises 

We  may  note  in  passing  that  the  Bank  successfully  weath- 
ered the  commercial  crises  of  1763,  1772  and  1783,  and  the 
directors  learned  by  experience  "  that  while  a  drain  of  specie 
is  going  on  their  issues  should  be  contracted  as  much  as 
possible,  but  that  as  soon  as  the  tide  had  given  signs  of  ceasing 
and  turning  the  other  way  it  was  then  safe  to  extend  their 
issues  freely."  The  control  in  normal  times  of  the  inflow  and 
outflow  of  specie  by  raising  or  lowering  the  bank  rate  of  dis- 
count was  another  lesson  which  the  managers  learned  and 
have  ever  since  used  effectively,  except  during  the  suspension 
of  specie  payments  during  and  following  the  French  wars  and 
the  practical  suspension  of  such  payments  since  1914. 

The  industrial  revolution  in  England  in  the  latter  part  of 
the  eighteenth  century,  due  to  the  invention  of  labour  saving 
devices  and  the  discovery  of  new  processes  of  manufacture, 
led  to  a  concentration  of  population,  to  great  activity  in  manu- 
factures and  in  commerce  and  hence  to  the  need  for  banking 
facilities  on  an  enlarged  scale.  As  joint-stock  banks  were 
prohibited,  as  more  fully  explained  in  a  later  chapter,  this 
need  was  supplied  by  many  small  banks  of  issue  and  deposit 
organized  by  six  persons  or  less — shop-keepers,  chemists, 
tailors  and  bakers,  or  what  not.  The  country  and  city 
were  thus  flooded  with  circulating  notes  of  weak  banking 
partnerships.  Many  of  these  issues  proved  to  be  worthless. 
From  1750  to  1783  the  country  banks  increased  from  twelve 
to  four  hundred.  In  the  crises  of  1793  and  1797  many  of 
these  banks  failed. 


CHAPTER  IV 

THE  BANK  AND  THE  GREAT  FRENCH  WAR 

In  1793  when  England  was  drawn  into  the  maelstrom  of 
war  in  Continental  Europe,  brought  about  by  the  French 
Revolution,  the  Bank  was  in  a  strong  condition.  Its  capital 
had  reached  £11,786,000 — all  loaned  to  the  Government.  It 
had  a  surplus  ("  The  Rest  ")  of  over  £3  million.  It  had  notes 
outstanding  for  £11,600,000.  Its  specie  reserve  was  about 
£5  million.  William  Pitt  was  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer. 
The  war  came  to  him  and  to  his  confreres  as  a  surprise.  The 
English  people  had  been  watching  the  revolutionary  pro- 
ceedings in  France  with  great  interest.  They  had  not 
expected  that  England  would  be  involved.  Pitt  and  his 
Government  had  made  all  their  plans  for  a  long  period  of 
peace  in  which  to  recover  fully  from  the  losses  of  the  American 
War  which  were  still  keenly  felt. 

Therefore  the  determination  to  engage  in  war  with  France 
found  the  Government  unprepared,  the  Exchequer  empty, 
or  relatively  so,  and  the  country  still  aghast  at  the  burden 
of  debt  which  had  accrued  from  the  American  War  and  the 
other  wars  of  the  eighteenth  century.  General  business 
conditions  were  bad,  due  to  a  succession  of  bad  harvests  and 
the  culmination  of  a  period  of  over-trading.  Many  country 
bank  failures  were  occurring.  The  Bank  of  England  itself 
became  alarmed,  contracted  its  credits  and  raised  the  rate  of 
discount.  To  relieve  the  situation  the  Government  had  found 
it  necessary  to  authorize  a  special  issue  of  Exchequer  bills  to 
be  loaned  to  merchants. 

It  was  in  the  midst  of  such  financial  conditions  that  Pitt 
was  forced  to  find  the  means  with  )^hich  to  finance  the  war 
needs  of  England  and  her  allies.  Great  sums  must  be  sent 
abroad  for  subsidies  and  for  the  support  and  pay  of  the  army 
and  of  the  navy.  The  Finance  Minister  and  the  City  had  a 
very  difficult  situation  with  which  to  deal — depleted  resources, 

161 

11— (1823) 


162  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

adverse  exchanges,  heavily  increased  demands.  Under  the 
circumstances  it  is  small  wonder  that  Pitt  used  the  resources 
of  the  Bank  to  the  limit.  He  first  secured  legislation  removing 
the  restriction  which  Parliament  had  originally  laid  upon 
advances  from  the  Bank  to  the  State.  The  Bank  was  then 
at  his  mercy.  In  four  years,  from  1794  to  1797  inclusive,  the 
debt  of  the  Government  to  the  Bank  for  advances  of  various 
kinds  totalled  just  under  £10  million  sterhng.  To  meet  the 
demands  upon  it  the  Bank  increased  its  note  issues.  Mean- 
while its  cash  resources  were  runnmg  down  in  an  alarming  way. 
After  increasing  to  about  £1  million  in  1794,  they  fell  to 
£6  million  in  February,  1795,  to  £5  million  in  August,  to  an 
average  of  a  little  over  £2  million  in  1796  and  finally  to 
£1,086,000  in  February,  1797. 

Specie  Payments  Suspended  1 797-1 821 

The  inevitable  happened.  Specie  payments  were  sus- 
pended, not  to  be  resumed  until  1821.  For  a  quarter  of  a 
century  England  was  to  experiment  with  an  inconvertible 
currency. 

The  King  himself  presided  at  the  meeting  of  the  Privy 
Council  which  authorized  the  suspension.  A  meeting  of 
bankers  and  merchants  passed  a  resolution  agreeing  to  accept  the 
notes  of  the  Bank  for  payments  due  to  them.  This  resolution 
was  supported  by  some  four  thousand  signatures.  The  matter 
was  referred  to  Parliament  for  action.  An  examination  hy  a 
parliamentary  committee  disclosed  the  fact  that  in  addition 
to  the  permanent  debt  of  £11,700,000  represented  by  its 
capital,  the  Bank  had  loaned  the  State  over  £10  million  out  of 
its  other  assets  of  £17,600,000  leaving  as  an  offset  against 
£13,800,000  demand  liabilities  and  about  £8,600,000  notes, 
about  £7,600,000  of  banking  assets  other  than  obligations  of 
the  Government.  Not  exactly  a  liquid  condition,  especially 
when  it  is  remembered  that  the  specie  reserve  had  fallen  to 
£1,086,000.  Substantially  all  of  the  floating  debt  of  the  State 
was  then  held  by  the  Bank. 

How  was  this  situation  dealt  with  ?     Parliament  passed 


•     THE    BANK   AND   THE   GREAT   FRENCH    WAR  163 

what  is  known  as  the  Restriction  Act.  This  granted  the  Bank 
and  all  connected  with  it  a  bill  of  indemnity.  The  Bank  was 
forbidden  to  pay  out  specie  except  for  the  needs  of  the  army 
and  navy  and  for  other  special  purposes  approved  by  the 
Privy  Council.  The  Bank  was  forbidden  during  the  restric- 
tion to  make  advances  for  the  public  service  in  excess  of 
£600,000.  Bank  notes  were  made  legal  tender  in  payment 
to  the  Government  and  between  others  by  agreement.  Pro- 
vision was  made  for  the  issue  of  £1  and  £2  notes  and,  for 
smaller  payments,  Spanish  dollars  were  put  in  circulation,  at 
a  valuation  of  4s.  6d. 

Pitt  threw  all  his  influence  in  favour  of  the  conservation 
of  the  Bank's  credit,  so  that  during  the  remainder  of  his  life- 
time there  were  no  excessive  issues  of  notes.  Therefore  they 
remained  substantially  at  par  with  gold.  After  Pitt's  death, 
from  1809  to  1817,  the  issues  of  notes  were  steadily  increased. 
This  course  of  action  was  due  partly  to  the  exigencies  of  the 
Government  and  partly  to  the  speculative  conditions  in  the 
business  world. 

It  will  be  remembered  that  Napoleon  endeavoured  to  bring 
England  to  her  knees  by  closing  to  her  all  the  Continental 
ports  and  markets.  While  such  closing  was  only  partial,  as 
many  ways  were  found  of  evading  the  edict,  still  it  acted  as  a 
great  stimulus  to  the  home  production  of  articles  which  would 
otherwise  have  been  imported.  At  the  same  time  the  South 
American  colonies  of  Spain  and  Portugal  were  declaring  their 
independence  and  opening  their  ports  to  English  products. 
These  conditions  led  to  speculation,  which  the  Bank  encour- 
aged by  greatly  expanding  its  credit  facilities.  These 
facilities  were  further  accentuated  by  the  large  amounts  of 
Exchequer  bills  put  out  by  the  Government,  plus  the  con- 
siderable sum  of  inland  bills  of  exchange  which  was  in  use  and 
the  country  banks'  bills  which  were  in  circulation. 

Effects  of  the  Suspension 

Advancing  prices  of  commodities,  including  gold,  and 
adverse  foreign  exchanges  were  the  barometers  which  measured 


1  Year. 

i 

s. 

Year 

1810 

.      13 

9 

1816 

1811 

7 

16 

to 

1812 

.  20 

4 

1818. 

1813 

.  22 

18 

1819 

1814 

.   25 

3 

1820 

1815 

.   16 

14 

164  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

the  inflation  produced  by  the  large  issues  of  bank  and 
Government  paper.  According  to  Toake,  after  being  at  a 
discount  of  £8  7s.  per  £100  in  1801  and  £1  5s.  in  1802,  Bank 
Notes  were  almost  at  par  (average  £2  13s.  discount)  from  1803 
to  1809.  The  depreciation  then  became  marked,  averaging 
as  follows,  until  the  resumption  of  specie  payments  in  1821 — 


2    13 

4      9 
2     12 

^  Years  ending  1st  Februarj'. 

Silberling,  by  another  basis  of  computation,  arrived  at  the 
conclusion  that  the  premium  on  gold  in  1811  averaged  nearly 
22  per  cent.,  in  1812  over  32  per  cent.,  in  1813  over  40  per 
cent.  The  Hamburg  exchanges  averaged  18  per  cent,  from 
normal  in  1810,  nearly  31  per  cent,  in  1811,  over  24  per  cent, 
in  1812,  and  over  26  per  cent,  in  1813.  Commodity  prices 
advanced  until  about  1814,  averaging  at  their  highest  point 
about  70  per  cent,  above  those  of  the  pre-war  period. 

The  Bullion  Report 

In  1810  a  committee  of  Parliament  known  as  the  "  Bullion 
Committee  "  made  an  exhaustive  study  of  the  causes  which 
had  produced  these  conditions,  so  far  as  they  had  then 
developed.  The  report  of  this  committee  is  one  of  the  land- 
marks on  the  highway  of  economic  studies  and  is  well  known 
to  all  students.  Therefore,  we  may  to  advantage  refer 
briefly  to  the  conclusions  of  the  committee  as  set  forth  in 
the  report.  The  points  in  controversy  which  they  set  them- 
selves to  solve  were  these  :  Have  the  bank  notes  depreciated 
in  value  or  has  the  price  of  gold  actually  risen  ?  Has  the 
increase  in  the  volume  of  the  notes  had  any  influence  upon  the 
exchanges  ?  What  effect  would  a  restriction  of  the  issues  have 
on  the  price  of  gold  and  the  rate  of  the  exchanges  ?  What 
policy  should  be  followed  in  regard  to  the  regulation  of  the 


THE    BANK    AND   THE    GREAT    FRENCH    WAR  165 

issues  ?  The  committee  called  before  them  bank  directors, 
private  bankers,  merchants  and  others.  The  conclusions  at 
which  they  arrived  were  these  :  First,  that  an  inconvertible 
and  excessive  credit  currency  caused  a  general  rise  in  prices, 
including  that  of  gold,  and  a  fall  in  the  exchanges  on  all  coun- 
tries except  those  which  had  an  equally  depreciated  currency. 
Second,  that  there  then  existed  an  excessive  paper  currency. 
Third,  that  the  only  true  and  proper  remedy  was  resumption 
of  cash  payments. 

Unfortunately  Parliament  took  an  opposite  view  of  the 
case.  This  encouraged  the  increasing  issues  on  the  part  of 
the  Bank,  leading  to  the  conditions,  up  to  1817,  which  we 
have  already  noted. 

Resumption  of  Specie  Payments  in  1821 

These  conditions  referred  to  were  so  serious  that  on  3rd 
February,  1819,  the  two  Houses  of  Parliament  each  appointed 
a  committee  to  inquire  into  the  position  of  the  Bank.  These 
committees,  after  hearing  the  views  of  bankers,  publicists 
and  others,  recommended  a  gradual  resumption  of  specie 
payments.  In  piusuance  of  their  recommendations  an  Act 
was  passed  unanimously  in  1819  providing  for  the  resumption 
of  specie  payments  on  1st  May,  1823.  This  date  was  antici- 
pated by  two  years,  the  metallic  basis  again  becoming  effective 
1st  May,   1821. 


CHAPTER  V 

THE   JOINT-STOCK   BANKS 

In  1697,  Parliament  evidently  intended  to  give  the  Bank  a 
virtual  monopoly,  since  no  other  corporation  of  the  nature 
of  a  bank  was  to  be  established  thereafter  by  Act  of  Parlia- 
ment. However,  this  Act  did  not  forbid  the  formation  of 
joint -stock  companies  for  other  purposes  nor  forbid  them  to 
undertake  a  banking  business.  Shortly  thereafter  a  corpora- 
tion, called  the  Company  of  Mine  Adventurers  of  England, 
issued  circulating  notes,  and  apparently  in  so  doing  was  quite 
within  its  legal  rights  under  the  Act  of  1697.  In  1708,  to  clear 
up  this  situation  Parliament  enacted,  "  That  during  the  con- 
tinuance of  the  said  corporation  of  the  Governor  and 
Company  of  the  Bank  of  England,  it  shall  not  be  lawful  for  any 
body  politic  or  corporate  whatsoever  ...  or  for  any  other 
persons  whatsoever,  united  or  to  be  united  in  covenants 
or  partnerships,  exceeding  the  number  of  six  persons,  in  that 
part  of  Great  Britain  called  England,  to  borrow,  owe,  or  take 
up  any  sum  or  sums  of  money  on  their  bills  or  notes  payable 
at  demand,  or  at  any  time  less  than  six  months  from  the 
borrowing  thereof." 

As  the  issuing  of  notes  was  at  that  time  considered  to 
be  the  very  essence  of  banking,  this  Act  was  popularly 
taken  to  forbid  the  organization  of  any  other  bank.  In  fact 
it  only  forbade  the  organization  of  banks  of  issue  by 
strong  corporations,  but  left  the  door  open  for  any  group 
of  six  persons  or  less,  however  irresponsible,  to  engage  in 
banking  and  to  issue  notes.  It  was  thus  that  the  great  num- 
ber of  mushroom  country  banks  came  into  being  whose  failure 
precipitated  or  accentuated  commercial  crises  for  more  than  a 
century  and  whose  note  issues  increased  the  redundancy 
of  the  currency  during  the  period  of  the  suspension  of  specie 
payments. 

By  an  Act  passed  in  1826  Corporate  Banks  of  Issue  were 

166 


THE   JOINT- STOCK   BANKS  167 

permitted  if  located  more  than  65  miles  from  London.  This 
continued  to  be  the  law  mitil  1844  when  Parliament  deprived 
both  private  and  joint-stock  banks  of  the  right  of  issue 
as  explained  in  the  next  chapter  discussing  the  Bank  Act  of 
1844.  However,  those  actually  in  existence — ^viz  :  72  joint- 
stock  banks  and  207  private  banks — retained  limited  privi- 
leges of  note  issue.  The  law  provided  that  as  such  privileges 
lapsed  they  should  accrue  to  the  Bank  of  England.  At  the 
present  time  (1920)  only  six  private  banks  and  three  joint- 
stock  banks  have  issue  rights  and  the  aggregate  authorized 
issues  of  these  banks  is  only  £334,820. 

In  1833  Parliament  affirmed  the  legality  of  joint -stock 
banks  which  issued  cheques.  The  Bank  of  England  had 
vainly  endeavoured  to  prevent  the  passage  of  such  legislation. 
Steps  were  at  once  taken  by  James  W.  Gilbart  and  associates 
to  organize  "  The  London  and  Westminster  Bank."  This 
bank  was  opened  at  38  Throgmorton  Street,  with  a  branch  at 
9  Waterloo  Place.  In  its  prospectus  it  was  stated  that  the 
bank  would  receive  current  accounts  and  that  persons  who 
did  not  care  to  keep  a  balance  might  "  instead  thereof,  pay  to 
the  bank  a  certain  sum  annually  for  the  management  of  their 
account."  Interest  at  the  rate  of  2  per  cent,  per  annum  was 
offered  on  sums  ranging  from  £10  to  £1,000  received  on 
"  permanent  lodgment."  No  interest  was  allowed  on  the 
balance  of  a  current  account. 

In  1832  there  were  62  private  banks  in  London.  In  1834 
the  number  of  private  country  banks  and  branches  thereof 
in  England  and  Wales  was  638  and  there  were  45  joint-stock 
banks.  Therefore,  at  or  about  the  time  of  the  organization 
of  the  London  and  Westminster  Bank,  there  were  in  England 
about  745  banks  and  banking  offices  in  addition  to  the  Bank 
of  England  and  its  12  branches.  We  are  without  information 
as  to  the  resources  of  these  banks,  other  than  the  Bank  of 
England.  It  is  of  interest  to  note  that  the  London  and 
Westminster  by  amalgamation  with  the  London  and  County 
in  1908  became  The  London  County  and  Westminster  Bank 
which  absorbed  Parr's  Bank  in  1918,  when  the  name  was 


168 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


changed  to  The  London  County  Westminster  and  Parr's  Bank, 
which  according  to  a  recent  report  had  147  offices  in  London 
alone  and  630  in  the  Provinces,  besides  several  foreign  offices. 
The  joint-stock  banks  of  England  and  Wales  now  number 
only  about  22  and  the  private  banks  7 — say,  about  29  in  all — 
but  they  have  in  the  neighbourhood  of  6,300  branches.  This 
great  decrease  in  the  number  of  banks  and  increase  in  branches 
is  due  to  the  policy  of  bank  consolidations  which  has  been  a 
marked  feature  of  English  banking  for  so  many  years  and 
especially  during  the  last  two  or  three  years.  On  31st 
December,  1919,  the  total  resources  of  the  joint-stock  banks 
of  England  and  Wales  were  about  ;£2,300  million.  Of  these 
vast  resources,  £1,742  million — say,  76  per  cent. — were  held 
by  five  great  banks.  In  alphabetic  sequence,  these  banks, 
their  liabilities  and  equivalent  resources  on  31st  December, 
1919,  were  as  follows — 

THE  "BIG  FIVE"  JOINT-STOCK  BANKS. 
In  Millions  Sterling. 


Capital 

Accept- 
ances and 

Deposits 
(including 

Total 

Name. 

and 

Endorse- 

Undivided 

Liabilities. 

Reserves. 

ments. 

Profits, 
etc.). 

Barclays 

15,8 

13.6 

296,1 

325,5 

Lloyds 

19,1 

32,1 

325,9 

377,1 

London  County,   West- 

minster and  Parr's    . 

17,3 

23,7 

305,8 

346,8 

London  Joint  City  and 

Midland 

16,8 

29,0 

373,0 

418,8 

National  Provincial  and 

Union 

15,0 

6,0 

252,4 

273,4 

84,0 

104,4 

1553,2 

1741,6 

CHAPTER  VI 

THE   BANK   CHARTER  ACT  OF    1844 

Before  taking  up  the  consideration  of  the  legislation  of 
1844  we  may  make  note  here,  for  the  sake  of  the  record,  of 
some  items  of  importance  in  regard  to  the  Bank.  The 
liability  of  the  stockholders  of  the  Bank  of  England  is  limited 
to  the  amount  of  their  stock.  In  1722  the  reserve  fund  or 
Rest  was  established,  never  to  be  allowed  to  run  below  £3 
million.  This  added  to  the  strength  of  the  Bank  and  made 
it  possible  to  equalize  dividends  which  theretofore  had 
fluctuated  greatly.  In  1751  the  administration  of  the  debt 
was  entrusted  to  the  Bank  and  in  1826  the  Bank  was  given 
authority  to  establish  branches  ;  of  these,  there  are  now 
ten,  located  respectively  at  Birmingham,  Bristol,  Hull, 
Leeds,  Liverpool,  Manchester,  Newcastle,  Plymouth,  and  the 
Western  and  Law  Courts  Branches,  London.  The  notes 
of  the  Bank  were  made  legal  tender  in  1833. 

Bank  Statements  in  England 

In  1833  the  Bank  was  required  to  render  weekly  state- 
ments to  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer,  which  statements 
were  to  be  consolidated  and  published  every  three  months  in 
the  London  Gazette.  The  statements  published  by  the  Bank 
are  very  meagre  and  do  not  give  one  a  complete  view  of  its 
affairs.  For  comparison  of  one  period  with  another,  too,  they 
are  of  little  value,  as  it  is  the  practice  of  the  Bank  to  reduce 
the  amount  of  its  securities  and  deposits  by  any  borrowing 
which  it  carries  out  and  as  it  probably  makes  other  adjust- 
ments which  are  not  of  public  record.  After  1875  it 
discontinued  publishing  the  amount  of  discounted  bills  which 
it  held.  After  1877  it  ceased  publishing  the  London  bankers' 
balances.  After  1880  the  separation  formerly  made  between 
notes  issued  by  the  branches  and  in  London  was  no  longer 

169 


170  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

made.  To  an  American  banker  accustomed  to  the  rigid 
supervision  given  to  the  affairs  of  the  banks  of  the  United 
States  by  State  and  Federal  governments  and  to  the  hme- 
light  of  publicity  which  is  turned  on  the  affairs  of  our  banks 
the  lack  of  such  supervision  in  Great  Britain  and  the  failure 
to  require  publicity  is  a  surprise.  It  is  because  of  such  failure 
to  enjoin  any  uniform  system  of  accounting  or  of  reporting 
that  it  is  so  difficult  to  make  a  really  thorough  and  scientific 
study  of  English  banking.  Apropos  of  this  the  London 
Economist  in  its  Banking  Number  issued  17th  May,  1919,  says  : 
"  The  figures  published  weekly  by  the  Bank  are  at  all  times 
full  of  snares  for  the  unwary  investigator,  and  are  more  so 
than  ever  in  wartime,  owing  to  the  very  complicated  business 
that  has  to  be  done  by  the  Bank,  and  the  consequent  cross 
currents  that  are  concealed  behind  the  inarticulate  reticence 
of  the  items  in  its  return.  Any  future  historian  who  relies  too 
closely  on  the  Bank's  figures  for  information  is  thus  likely 
to  flounder  up  to  his  neck." 

The  Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844 

Recurrent  commercial  crises,  and  especially  the  crisis  of 
1836-1839,  led  English  bankers  and  economists  of  the  time 
to  make  exhaustive  studies  of  the  causes  of  such  events. 
The  rule  which  had  been  formulated  by  the  Bank  for  the 
conduct  of  its  business  was  as  follows  :  First,  the  reserve 
kept,  composed  of  bullion  and  of  securities,  was  to  be  equal 
to  its  liabilities.  Second,  the  regulation  of  the  note  circulation 
was  left  to  the  public  through  the  natural  movement  of  the 
foreign  exchanges.  Third,  whether  the  demands  on  the  Bank 
came  from  at  home  or  abroad,  it  was  to  maintain  a  metallic 
reserve  equal  to  one-third  of  its  liabilities.  This  supposed 
rule  it  was  difficult  invariably  to  observe.  In  fact  it  was 
often  broken. 

A  heavy  drain  of  specie  in  1839  carried  down  the  reserve 
to  a  nominal  amount.  The  condition  of  the  Bank  became 
so  serious  that  it  was  necessary,  in  order  to  meet  the  emer- 
gency, to  resort  to  special  measures,  the  most  important  of 


THE    BANK   CHARTER   ACT   OF    1844  171 

which  was  a  large  loan  from  the  Bank  of  France  which  had 
been  founded  in  1800  by  Napoleon. 

It  was  evident  to  the  thoughtful  banking  men  of  the  day, 
and  to  other  students  of  finance,  that  steps  must  be  taken  to 
safeguard  the  Bank's  reserves  in  future.  It  was  desirable  also, 
if  possible,  to  stop  these  recurring  periods  of  distress  in  the 
business  world.  Following  a  customary  English  method  for 
dealing  with  difl&cult  problems,  a  parliamentary  committee 
was  appointed  to  examine  into  the  causes  of  the  trouble  and  to 
suggest  a  remedy.  This  committee  sat  for  over  five  years  and 
asked  more  than  14,000  questions  without  reaching  any 
definite  conclusion  or  even  presenting  a  report.  Finally,  Sir 
Robert  Peel,  then  Prime  Minister,  decided  that  it  was  time 
to  bring  matters  to  a  head.  Therefore,  taking  advantage  of 
a  clause  in  the  law  which  empowered  the  Government  to 
suspend  the  Bank's  charter  in  1845,  he  brought  forward  a 
bill  which  became  the  Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844. 

Convinced  that  the  source  of  the  trouble  was  due  to  over- 
issues of  cmrency,  he  sought  to  devise  a  plan  which  would 
cure  this  evil.  He  proposed  to  take  away  from  the  private 
and  joint-stock  banks  the  right  of  issue  and  to  concentrate 
all  such  rights  in  the  Bank  of  England.  Further  to  guard 
against  over-issues  he  proposed  that,  save  for  a  minimum 
amount,  all  issues  of  the  Bank  should  be  covered  by  an 
equivalent  amount  of  specie,  especially  reserved  for  their 
redemption. 

Provisions  of  the  Act 

The  law  based  on  these  propositions  provided  as  follows  : 
1.  After  31st  August,  1844,  the  Bank  of  England  was  to  be 
divided  into  two  departments,  the  issue  department  and  the 
banking  department.  Securities  to  the  amount  of  £14  million, 
of  which  the  perpetual  Government  debt  of  £11  million  was 
to  form  a  part,  were  to  be  transferred  to  the  issue  department  ; 
also  all  the  gold  coin  and  gold  and  silver  bullion  not  needed 
in  the  banking  department.  The  issue  department  was 
to  give  back  to  the  banking  department  an  amount  of  notes 


172  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

equal  to  the  securities,  coin  and  bullion  so  transferred  to  it. 
It  was  provided  that  the  silver  in  the  issue  department  should 
never  exceed  one-fourth  of  the  gold. 

2.  The  limited  rights  of  issue  continued  to  bankers  already 
having  such  rights,  as  they  lapsed,  were  to  the  extent  of 
two-thirds  thereof  to  revert  to  the  Bank.  Thus  it  is  that 
to-day  the  Bank  has  a  right  of  issue  against  securities  of 
£4,450,000  in  excess  of  the  original  £14  million. 

3.  The  Bank  was  exempted  from  all  stamp  duties  on  its 
notes.  In  lieu  thereof  it  was  to  pay  the  Government  a  lump 
sum  of  £180,000  a  year. 

4.  The  Bank  was  obligated  to  buy  standard  gold  when- 
ever offered  to  it,  giving  in  payment  its  notes  at  £3  17s.  9d. 
per  ounce. 

5.  Weekly  accounts  in  a  specified  form  were  to  be  sent  to 
the  Government  and  published  in  the  London  Gazette  weekly, 
instead  of  quarterly  as  required  by  the  Act  of  1833. 

This  division  of  the  functions  of  the  Bank  into  two  depart- 
ments has  been  severely  criticized  as  arbitrary  and  unscientific. 

Suspensions  of  the  Act 

The  result  of  the  legislation  was  to  put  the  management 
of  the  Bank  in  times  of  crises  in  a  strait-jacket,  as  far  as  notes 
were  concerned,  from  which  they  could  escape  only  by  special 
enabling  legislation  by  Parliament.  This  has  been  had  four 
times  in  the  history  of  the  Bank — in  1847,  in  1857,  in  1866  and 
in  1914.  The  mere  fact  that  additional  notes  could  be  issued 
has  of  itself,  in  each  case,  been  sufficient  to  allay  the  fears  of 
the  business  community.  The  increase  made  in  the  amount 
of  uncovered  note  issue  in  the  earlier  periods  was  trifling, 
while  in  the  last  instance  an  important  increase  was  made 
unnecessary  by  the  issuance  of  the  Government  Treasmy 
notes.  As  a  matter  of  record  it  may  be  noted  that  for  a  couple 
of  days  while  Treasury  notes  were  being  printed  there  was 
an  excess  fiduciary  issue  of  Bank  notes  amounting  to 
£3,043,000. 

Under  the  Federal  Reserve  System  of  the  United  States 


THE   BANK   CHARTER  ACT  OF    1844  173 

and  of  the  Continental  state  banks,  notes  are  created  and 
issued  on  the  security  of  discounted  bills  and  on  the  specie 
reserve.  Thus  theoretically  the  volume  of  notes  is  responsive 
to  the  requirements  of  business,  expanding  and  contracting 
with  the  periods  of  activity  and  quietude.  On  the  contrary, 
with  the  Bank  of  England  the  note  issue  can  only  be  in- 
creased against  the  deposit  of  specie  in  the  issue  department. 
This  can  be  accomplished  only  by  a  transfer  of  gold  from  the 
Banking  Department,  in  which  department  as  a  rule  only  a 
small  amount  of  gold  is  held,  or  by  obtaining  gold  from  the 
Joint  Stock  Banks  or  by  buying  new  gold  in  the  market. 
Whatever  method  is  used,  except  the  purchasing  of  new  gold, 
reduces  the  amount  of  gold  in  circulation  or  reduces  the  reserve 
upon  which  the  credit  or  deposit  currency  of  the  country  is 
based,  and  this  has  the  effect  of  diminishing  the  credit  facilities 
at  the  service  of  the  business  community  just  at  a  time  when 
the  contrary  conditions  should  prevail.  Therefore  there  is 
a  growing  feeling  on  the  part  of  many  bankers  that  the  two 
departments  of  the  Bank  should  be  merged  and  the  note 
issuing  powers  modernized. 

However,  in  times  of  great  stress,  such  as  the  world  has  just 
been  passing  through,  the  best  of  systems  tends  to  give  way 
to  emergency  measures  which  cannot  be  defended  on  any 
principle  of  sound  banking.  The  Bank  of  England  has  come 
through  the  storm  in  strong  condition  and  has  done  yeoman 
service  in  upholding  the  hands  of  the  Government  and  of  the 
business  community.  This  does  not  change  the  fact  that 
upon  a  return  to  normal  conditions  it  may  be  wise  definitely  to 
repeal  the  Act  of  1844  in  favour  of  a  system  based  upon 
banking  experience  gained  since  that  time. 


CHAPTER  VII 

THE   GOVERNMENT  OF  THE   BANK 

The  method  by  which  the  Bank  of  England  is  governed 
is  so  unique  and  so  different  from  that  observed  in  con- 
nection with  any  other  bank  that  it  wiU  be  of  interest  to 
consider  it  in  some  detail.  The  bank  is  governed  by  a  Board 
of  twenty-four  directors,  a  Governor  and  a  Deputy  Governor. 

The  Directorate 

The  Board  of  Directors  is  self -electing.  In  theory,  a  certain 
portion  go  out  annually,  remain  out  a  year,  and  are  subject  to 
re-election  by  the  proprietors,  but  in  fact  they  are  nearly 
always  re-elected  after  a  year.  This  has  been  the  unbroken 
practice  for  many  years.  When  a  vacancy  occurs  by  death 
or  resignation  it  is  filled  by  an  election  by  the  Board.  It  is 
the  practice  in  electing  new  members  to  choose  young  men, 
usually  men  connected  with  old  established  mercantile  firms 
of  London.  The  status  which  is  given  by  an  election  to  the 
Board,  both  to  the  individual  who  fills  it  and  to  the  firm  of 
merchants  to  which  he  belongs,  is  considerable.  The  selection 
of  men  to  receive  this  honour  is  made  with  great  Care  for  a 
reason  which  will  now  be  stated. 

The  Governor  and  Deputy  Governor 

The  ofhccs  of  Governor  and  Deputy  Governor  are  given 
in  rotation.  The  Deputy  Governor  always  succeeds  the 
Governor  and  usually  the  oldest  Director  who  has  not  been 
in  office  becomes  Deputy  Governor.  Occasionally,  for 
special  reasons,  the  election  for  the  Deputy  Governor  is  not 
always  made  in  rotation,  but  except  in  rare  cases  a  Director 
must  serve  as  Governor  and  Deputy  Governor  about  the  time 
when  his  turn  comes.  On  the  other  hand,  he  will  not  be  asked 
to  serve  much  before  his  turn.  It  is  usually  about  twenty 
years  from  the  time  a  man  is  first  elected  a  Director  before  he 

174 


THE   GOVERNMENT  OF   THE   BANK  175 

arrives,  as  it  is  called,  "  at  the  Chair."  Because  it  is  impor- 
tant that  the  men  who  fill  the  offices  of  Governor  and  Deputy 
Governor  should  still  be  in  the  vigour  of  life,  the  choice  of  new 
Directors  is  always  made  from  among  young  men.  It  might 
be  feared  that  such  a  course  would  place  upon  the  Board  men 
who  would  be  over-ambitious  or  would  take  chances  which 
older  men  would  not  take,  but  the  danger  of  such  a  happening 
is  overcome  by  the  fact  that  some  of  the  Directors  retire 
annually.  By  courtesy  it  is  always  the  young  Directors. 
Those  who  have  served  as  Governor  always  remain.  There- 
fore the  young  part  of  the  Board  is  the  fluctuating  part,  and 
the  older  part  is  the  permanent  part.  The  younger  men, 
therefore,  have  but  little  influence. 

The  Committee  of  Treasury 

As  a  further  provision  against  any  immature  methods  of 
handling  the  affairs  of  the  Bank,  the  older  members  of  the 
Board  form  a  standing  committee  of  indefinite  powers.  This 
is  called  the  Committee  of  Treasury.  No  precise  description 
has  ever  been  given  of  the  powers  which  this  committee 
exercises.  They  appear  to  be  of  a  general  supervisory  nature 
and  in  particular  to  control  the  relations  and  negotiations 
between  the  Bank  and  the  Government. 

The  Officers 

In  the  Bank  of  England  there  is  no  fixed  Executive.  The 
Governor  and  Deputy  Governor  who  form  the  Executive,  as 
a  rule  change  every  two  years.  They  are  expected  to  be  con- 
stantly present  at  the  Bank,  to  see  all  applicants  for  advances, 
to  carry  on  the  almost  continuous  correspondence  between 
the  Bank  and  its  largest  customer,  the  Government,  and 
to  bring  all  necessary  matters  before  the  Comt  of  Directors 
or  the  Committee  of  Treasury.  In  a  word,  to  do  very  much 
the  sam^e  as  falls  to  the  lot  of  the  Manager  in  most  Companies. 
There  are,  of  course,  permanent  heads  of  departments,  and 
it  is  understood  that  during  the  war  some  important  new 
departments    were   created.     WTiile   these    men   have   high 


176  ENGLISH    PUBLIC    FINANCE 

standing  in  the  Bank  and  much  authority  in  their  respec- 
tive departments,  yet  they  are  essentially  subordinate. 
No  one  of  them  is  like  the  General  Manager  of  an  ordinary 
bank. 

A  changing  management,  such  as  the  one  by  which  the 
Bank  is  governed,  would  not  be  thought  of  in  connection 
with  any  other  corporation.  It  also  seems  strange  that 
until  recently  trained  bankers  should  have  been  excluded 
from  the  Board  of  Directors  of  the  Bank  which  up  to  the 
present  time  has  been  admittedly,  in  a  sense,  the  reserve 
Bank  for  the  world's  commerce. 

The  Court  and  Committees 

The  Directors  of  the  Bank,  together  with  the  Governor  and 
Deputy  Governor,  twenty-six  persons  in  all,  are  known  as 
"  The  Court."  They  meet  once  a  week  and  usually  sit  for 
a  very  short  time  only  ;  say,  from  about  eleven  or  twelve 
o'clock  until  one  or  one-thirty.  It  has  been  said  that  if  they 
were  to  sit  for  four  hours  there  would  be  a  "  panic  solely  from 
that." 

The  Court  of  Directors  is  divided  into  certain  committees. 
In  addition  to  the  Committee  of  Treasury  already  described, 
there  is  a  Committee  of  Daily  Waiting,  a  Committee  for  Law- 
suits and  the  Management  of  Branch  Banks,  a  Committee 
for  the  House  and  Servants  and  Clerks,  a  Committee  of 
Inspection  for  the  Cashier's  Office  and  a  Committee  of  Inspec- 
tion for  the  Accountants'  Office.  In  addition  to  these 
committees  special  committees  are  from  time  to  time  appointed 
as  occasion  may  require. 

The  Committee  of  Daily  Waiting  consists  of  three  Directors 
in  rotation  from  the  whole  body.  Their  attendance  is  at 
11.30  daily  and  they  are  required  to  remain  until  all  that  part 
of  the  business  of  the  day  which  is  usually  referred  to  them  is 
concluded.  All  bills  offered  for  discount  in  London  are 
submitted  to  this  committee  and  all  bills  discounted  at  the 
country  branches,  except  local  bills,  are  shown  to  them  on  the 
following  day.     They  likewise  have  charge  of  all  bullion  not 


THE    GOVERNMENT   OF   THE    BANK  177 

required  by  the  cashiers  for  daily  wants.     The  duties  of  the 
other  committees  arc  evident  from  their  titles. 

The  Clerical  Machinery 

The  clerical  machinery  of  the  Bank  is  divided  into  the 
"  Cash  Side  "  and  the  "  Accountant  Side."  The  "  Cash 
Side,"  which  is  under  the  immediate  supervision  of  the  Chief 
Cashier,  comprises  the  transaction  of  all  business  where  actual 
cash  is  concerned,  together  with  the  necessary  book-keeping 
which  it  involves.  The  latter  division,  under  charge  of  the 
Chief  Accountant,  takes  cognizance  of  all  matters  of  pure 
book-keeping  where  no  actual  cash  is  concerned,  such  as  those 
which  relate  to  the  national  debt  account,  registration  of 
bank  notes  and  kindred  work. 

The  Bank  has  a  large  staff  of  employees,  for  whose  benefit 
there  is  maintained  a  provident  society  to  promote  life  insur- 
ance among  their  members  and  the  payment  of  annuities  for 
widows  of  bank  clerks  and  porters.  There  is  a  well  appointed 
library  and  reading  room.  There  is  a  physician  in  attendance 
who  is  called  the  Medical  Ofhcer.  He  looks  after  the  health 
of  the  clerks  and  other  employees.  The  clerical  force  of  the 
Bank  is  employed  on  a  strictly  civil  service  or  competitive 
plan.  Men  entering  the  Bank  in  their  youth  frequently 
spend  their  entire  lives  in  its  service. 

The  Bank  Building 

The  building  of  the  Bank  of  England  is  located  in  the 
heart  of  what  is  known  as  "  the  City,"  the  corporate  centre 
of  London  now  chiefly  identified  with  the  interests  of  City 
Government  and  Finance.  In  this  section  is  the  Mansion 
House,  where  the  Mayor  presides  over  the  destinies  of  the 
City.  Near  by  is  the  Royal  Exchange  founded  in  the  days  of 
Queen  Elizabeth;  and  the  Stock  Exchange,  the  traditions  of 
which  also  date  back  to  the  very  early  days.  Lombard  Street, 
the  home  of  the  goldsmiths  and  for  many  years  the  chief 
financial  street  in  London,  is  near  by.  The  head  offices  of  the 
joint -stock  banks  and  of  the  great  private  banking  houses  are 
not  far  away. 

12— (1823) 


178  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

The  entrance  to  the  Bank  is  from  Threadneedle  Street 
through  a  large  arched  gateway  which  leads  into  a  quad- 
rangular court  from  which  communication  may  be  had  to  all 
parts  of  the  building.  This  court  is  guarded  by  a  porter 
arrayed  in  bright  crimson  and  gold  lace  and  bearing  a  staff ; 
while  the  Bank  messengers  are  dressed  in  swallow-tail  coats 
of  a  delicate  salmon  colour  with  silver  buttons,  flaming  scarlet 
waistcoats,  black  trousers  and  high  silk  hats. 

In  the  basement  of  the  Bank  are  barracks  wherein  36 
soldiers  are  quartered  from  7  o'clock  every  evening  until  the 
next  morning.  This  custom  arose  at  the  time  of  the  Lord 
George  Gordon  riots  in  June,  1780,  when  the  Bank  was  threat- 
ened by  a  mob.  In  addition  to  the  soldiers  there  is  a  body  of 
watchmen  well  trained  in  the  use  of  the  ample  arrangements 
provided  for  in  case  of  fire. 

The  building  covers  about  eight  acres  of  ground.  The  first 
stone  was  laid  in  1732.  It  is  erected  around  nine  courtyards, 
the  largest  one  of  which  has  a  substantial  amount  of  green 
sward  with  one  or  two  beautiful  elm  trees  and  some  shrubbery. 
There  is  also  a  fountain  playing  beneath  the  trees.  For  the 
first  forty  years  of  its  existence  the  Bank  was  domiciled  in  the 
hall  of  the  Grocers'  Company,  but  in  1734  moved  into  the 
present  building.  In  the  great  hall  of  the  Bank  building  there 
is  a  statue  of  William  III,  in  whose  reign,  it  will  be  remembered, 
the  Bank  was  founded. 


CHAPTER  VIII 

THE   SCOTCH  AND   IRISH   BANKS 

In  what  goes  before  we  have  confined  our  studies  to  the 
status  of  Banking,  to  use  the  words  of  one  of  the  Bank  Charter 
Acts,    "  in  that  part  of  Great  Britain  called  England." 

The  first  notice  of  Banking  in  Scotland  which  occurs  in 
the  statute  books  is  an  Act  of  King  William  III,  passed  in  1695, 
under  which  the  Bank  of  Scotland  was  established.  The 
Bank  of  Scotland  remained  the  only  bank  in  Scotland  until 
the  year  1727.  At  the  date  of  the  latest  available  reports 
(December,  1918)  there  were  eight  Joint-Stock  Banks  in  Scot- 
land with  1,249  branches.  These  banks  had  total  resources 
of  £273,658,000.  Their  combined  note  issues  on  31st 
December,  1919,  amounted  to  £28,705,345,  comparing  with 
£7,744,000  on  31st  December,  1913,  an  increase  of  £20,961,345. 

The  Bank  of  Ireland  was  established  in  1783,  Its  privi- 
leges resemble  those  of  the  Bank  of  England.  At  the  close 
of  1918  there  were  nine  Joint-Stock  Banks  in  Ireland  with  848 
branches  and  combined  resources  of  £175,739,000.  The  out- 
standing note  issues  on  31st  December,  1919,  were  £30,532,435, 
comparing  with  £8,074,000  on  31st  December,  1913,  an 
increase  of  £22,458,435. 

Note  Circulation — How  Regulated 

The  bank  note  circulation  of  the  Scotch  and  Irish  Banks 
is  regulated  by  the  Bank  Acts  of  1845.  These  Acts  authorized 
the  Scotch  Banks  to  make  uncovered,  or  fiduciar}^  issues  fixed 
at  an  aggregate  of  £3,087,209.  As  a  result  of  the  failure  of  the 
Western  Bank  of  Scotland  in  1858  and  of  the  City  of  Glasgow 
Bank  in  1878  the  authorized  fixed  issue  was  reduced  and  is 
now  £2,676,350.  The  Irish  Banks  were  authorized  to  make 
uncovered  issues  fixed  at  an  aggregate  of  £6,354,494.  There 
has  been  no  change  in  this  authorization. 

179 


180  ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 

The  Scotch  and  Irish  Banks  may  increase  their  circulation 
to  any  extent  in  accordance  with  the  pubhc  demand,  pro- 
vided that  they  have  gold  or  silver  at  their  principal  places  of 
issue  to  an  amount  not  less  than  the  amount  of  such  increase. 
The  amount  of  silver  against  which  notes  may  be  issued  must 
not  exceed  "  one-fourth  part  of  the  gold  coin  held." 

The  amount  of  notes  which  may  be  outstanding  against 
specie  is  determined  by  averaging  the  note  issues  and  the 
specie  cover  every  four  weeks.  This  provision  of  the  law 
makes  it  possible  temporarily  to  increase  note  issues  without 
corresponding    cover. 

The  specie  held  in  Scotland  and  Ireland  does  not  form  a 
special  security  against  the  note  circulation.  It  is  an  asset 
held  against  the  general  liabilities  of  the  issuing  bank.  It  will 
be  remembered  that  in  the  case  of  the  Bank  of  England  the 
specie  securing  the  notes  in  excess  of  the  fiduciary  issue  is  held 
in  the  issue  department  solely  as  a  reserve  for  the  notes  issued 
against  it,  while  no  notes  can  be  issued,  for  ever  so  brief  an 
interval,  unless  the  specie  is  actually  on  deposit. 

By  the  terms  of  the  Currency  and  Bank  Notes  Act  of 
6th  August,  1914,  the  note  issues  of  the  Scotch  and  Irish  Banks 
were  made  legal  tender  and  authority  was  given  to  substitute 
the  Government  Treasury  Notes  for  specie  as  a  cover  for  notes 
issued  in  excess  of  the  authorized  fixed,  or  fiduciary,  issues. 
By  a  royal  proclamation  made  in  December,  1919,  the  legal 
tender  status  was  withdrawn  from  Scotch  and  Irish  Bank  Notes 
to  take  effect  from  1st  January,  1920,  and  the  pre-war  status 
restored,  but  no  change  was  made  in  regard  to  the  provision 
whereby  Government  Treasury  Notes  may  be  used  as  cover  for 
the  note  issues  in  excess  of  the  fixed,  or  fiduciary,  totals. 


Tabl 


es 


NATIONAL  DEBT. 
United  Kingdom — Great  Britain  and  Ireland. 

Approximate  Amount — 31st  March,   1920. 

For  further  details  see  numbered  descriptive  notes  following  table. 
000  omitted. 


Title  of  Loan. 

Interest 
Rate.             Payable 

Redeemable 
or  Payable. 

Out- 
standing. 

Funded  Debt — 

(1)  ConsoUdated  Stock 

(2)  Annuities 

(3)  Annuities 

2i      5  Ja.,  Ap.,  Jy. 
2i      5Ja.,Ap.,  Jy. 
2i      5Ja.,Ap.,Jy., 

Oct 
Oct. 
Oct. 

After  5  April,  1923 
After  5  Jan.,    1905 
After  5  Jan..   1905 

i 
277,200 
2,600 
21,500 

(4)  Debt  to  Bank  of 

England 

(5)  Debt  to   Bank  of 

Ireland 

2t 
2} 

Total  Consols 

Perpetual 

Perpetual 

301,300 

11,000 

2,600 

(6)  Total  Funded  Debt    . 

(7)  Terminable  Annuities 

— Estimated  Capital 
Value  . 

(8)  Unfunded  Debt 

(9)  Ways  and   Means 

Advances 

(10)  War  Loan 

(11)  War  Loan 


12)  War  Loan 

(13)  War  Loan 
National  War  Bonds — 

(14)  First  Series 
First  Series 
First  Series 
First  Series 

(15)  Second  Series  . 
Second  Series  . 
Second  Series  . 
Second  Series    . 

(16)  Third  Series      . 
Third  Series 
Third  Series 
Third  Scries 

(17)  Fourth  Series  . 
Fourth  Series  . 
Fourth  Series    . 

(18)  Funding  Loan  . 

(19)  Victory  Bonds 

(20)  Exchequer  Bonds 
Exch  quer  Bonds 
Exchequer  Bonds 
Exchequer  Bonds 

Exchequer  Bonds 


1  Mar.  and  Sept. 

1  June  and  Dec. 

1  June  and  Dec. 

15  April  and  Oct. 

1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  April  and  Oct. 
1  Mar.  and  Sept. 
1  Mar.  and  Sept. 
1  Mar  and  Sept. 
1  Mar.  and  Sept. 
1  Feb.  and  Aug. 
1  Feb.  and  Aug. 
1  Feb.  and  Aug. 

4         1  May  <"nd  Nov. 

4  1  Mar.  and  Sept. 
3  28  Jan.  and  July 

5  1  June  and  Dec. 
5  5  .\pril  and  Oct. 
5  1  April  and  Oct. 

5i       1  Feb.  and  Aug. 


1925  > 
1  Mar.,  1928  5 


<  After  1  Mar, 
(On 

(  After  1  Dec,  1925 

(On  1  Dec,  1945 

<  After  1  June.  1929  ) 

<  On  1  June,  1947  \ 


w 


.  After  15  Oct., 
'  On      15  Oct., 


1929  : 
1942 


On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 
On 


1  Oct.,  1922  V 
1  Oct.,  1924 
1  Oct.,  1927 
1  Oct.,  1927 
1  Apr.,  1923 
1  Apr.,  1925 
1  Apr.  1928 
1  Apr.,  1928 
1  Sept, 1923 
1  Sept.,  1925 


1  Sept., 
1  Sept. 
1  Feb., 
1  Feb., 
1  Feb.. 


1928 
1928 
1924 
1929 
1929' 


<  After  1  May,  1960  ) 
(  On  1  May,  1990  ) 
After  1  Sept.,  1920 
On  28  Jan.,  1930  \ 
On  16  Dec,  1920  | 
On  S  Oct.,  1921  ' 
After  1  Oct.,  1919  f 
O  <  1  Apr.,  1922 
^"  I  1  Feb..  1925  ' 
But  see  note  (20). 


Carried  forward 


314,900 

19,300 

204,900 
62,700 

12,800 

1,977,100 

64,100 


1,475,800 


408,900 
359,500 


319,100 


5219,100 


*■  Total  correct — items  approximate 


181 


182 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 


NATIONAL  DEBT— Conlinued. 


United  Kingdom — Great  Britain  and  Ireland. 

Approximate  Amount — 31st  March,  1920. 


For  further  details  see  numbered  descriptive  notes  following  table. 
000  omitted. 


Title  of  Loan. 
Brought  forward 


Interest 
Rate.  Payable. 


Redeemable 
or  Payable. 


(21)  Treasury  Bills 

(22)  War  Savings  Certifi- 

cates   . 

(23)  Other  Capital 

Liabilities 
External  Debt — 

(24)  To  United  States 

Govt.  84,212,835,993 

(25)  Anglo-French  Loan 

$500,000,000     half 
taken  into  account     5 

(26)  Five     Year    Secured 

Notes,  $134,458,000    5i 

(27)  Three     Year     Conv. 

Notes,  $101,600,000    5J 
28)  Ten  Year  Conv.  Bonds 

$148,400,000  .     5| 

(29)  Twenty     Year    Gold 

Bonds,  $143,587,000   5J 

(30)  Other   Debt   Created 

under    War    Loan 
Acts     . 

Total  External  Debt 

Grand  Total  Direct  Debt 

(31)  Guaranteed  Loans — 
Guaranteed  Stock 

(created  under  Irish 


Out- 
standing. 

£5,219,100 

1,107,300 

273,500 

46,900 

865,600 


5  April  and  Oct. 

On 

15  Oct., 

1920 

51,400 

1  May  and  Nov. 

On 

1  Nov., 

,  1921 

26,500 

1  Feb.  and  Aug. 

On 

1  Nov. 

,1922 

20,900 

1  Feb.  and  Aug. 

On 

1  Aug., 

,  1929 

30,500 

1  Feb.  and  Aug. 

On 

1  Feb., 

1937 

29,500 
154,300 

£1,178,700 

£7,825,500 

Land  Act,  1903)     . 

2i% 

Jan.  and  July 

After    1  Nov.,  1933 

57,043 

Guaranteed  Stock 

(created  under  Irish 

Land     Acts,     1903 

and  1909)      . 

3 

Jan.  and  July 

After   3  Dec,  1939 

50,C40 

Local  Loans  Stock     . 

3 

5  Ja.,  Ap.,  Jy.,  Oct.    After       Apr.,  1912 

77,059 

Met.      Police      Deb. 

Stock   . 

3 

Jan.  and  July 

On        1  July,  1920 

450 

Egyptian  Government 

Guaranteed  Loan  . 

3 

Mar.  and  Sept. 

At  any  time. 

6,098 

Greek     Guar.      Gold 

Loan  of  '98  . 

2i 

April  and  Oct. 

Redeemable  at  par 
by  annual  drawings 

4,234 

Mauritius  Stock,  1914 

Guar,  by  Imp.  Gov. 

3 

1  Jan.  and  July 

On        1  Jan.,   1940 

600 

Soudan    Govt.    Gtd. 

Bonds  . 

51 

1  May  and  Nov. 

3.500 

Transvaal  Govt.  Gtd. 
Stock   . 

3 

1  May  and  Nov.    | 

After    1  May,  1923  > 
On        1  May,  1953  ] 

35,000 

Transvaal  Govt.  Gtd. 

Stock   . 

3  • 

1  Jan.  and  July 

On        1  July,  1958 

5,000 

Turkish     Guaranteed 

Loan    . 

4 

1  Feb.  and  Aug. 

1855 

3,815 

Total  Guaranteed  Debt 

243,439 

Grand  Total  Direct  and  Guaranteed  Debt 

£8,069,000 

NATIONAL    DEBT  183 

DESCRIPTIVE  NOTES. 

'*  Stock  "  =  Registered  Bonds  :   See  Item  32. 
Transfers,  Denominations,  etc.  :  See  Item  p.  186. 

(1)  Consolidated  Stock. — "Consols."  In  the  session  of  Parliament  of  1751-2  an  act 
was  passed  consolidating  five  different  loans  and  certain  annuities  into  one  joint  stock  of 
3%  annuities.  The  taxes  upon  which  the  interest  of  these  loans  was  charged  were  carried 
to  the  sinking  fund  out  of  which  the  annuities  were  made  payable  from  24th  June,  1752. 
This  was  the  origin  of  the  3%  Consolidated  annuities,  known  in  the  market  from  that  time 
as  "  Consols."  The  present  issue  of  2J%  "  Consols  "  was  created  under  the  terms  of  the 
National  Etebt  (Conversion)  Act  of  1888.  Up  to  5th  April,  1889,  interest  was  at  the  rate  of 
3%  per  annum,  and  for  the  14  years  ending  with  5th  April,  1903,  it  was  at  the  rate  of  2  j%. 
Since  that  date  the  rate  has  been  2i%.  Redeemable  at  par  on  or  after  5th  April,  1923,  in 
such  order  or  manner  as  Parliament  may  direct.     See  also  p.  105. 

(2)  2J%  Annuities  created  under  the  National  Debt  Conversion  of  Stock  Act,  1884. 

(3)  2J%  Annuities  created  in  1853  for  the  purpose  of  redeeming  South  Sea  stock  and 
certain  old  3%  annuities. 

(4)  Debt  to  the  Bank  of  England. — Perpetual  loans  made  in  consideration  of  franchise 
as  follows — 

Original  Capital.  £                   £ 

1694— Act  5  and  6  W.  and  M.  c.  20 1,200,000 

1708— Act  7  Anne,  c.  7 400,000 

1742— Act  15  G.  2,  c.  13 1,600,000 


3,200,000 


Capital  purchased  of  the  South  Sea  Co. 
1721— Act  8   G.    1.   c  21     (residue    of  capital  of  £4,000,000 

purchased  of  the  South  Sea  Company)  .         .  .  3,328,300 

Other  Advances  to  Government — 
1716— Act  G.  1  c.  8,  Balance  of  £2,000,000  of  Exchequer  Bills 

cancelled 500,000 

1717 — 1  G.  2,  c.  8,  Advance  to  Government     ....  1,750,000 

1728— 2  G.  2,  c.  3,  Advance  to  Government     ....  1,250,000 

1746 — 19    G.  2,  c.  6,    Exchequer    Bills    delivered    up    to    be 

cancelled 986,800 


£11,015,100 


(5)  Debt  to  the  Bank  of  Ireland. — Perpetual  loans  made  in  consideration  of  franchise 
as  follows — 

£  s.  d. 

1782— Act  21  and  22  G.  3  c.  16  (Irish)  (Irish  Currency,  £600,000)    .            553,846  3  1 

1797— Act  37  G.  3  c.  50  (Irish)  (Irish  Currency,  £500,000)       .          .            461,538  9  3 

1808— Act  48  G.  3  c.  103  (Irish  Currency,  £1,250,000)     .         .         .         1,153,846  3  1 

1821— Act  2  G.  3,  c.  72  (Irish  Currency,  £500,000)           .         .         .            461,538  9  3 

£2,630,769  4  8 


(6)  Total  Funded  Debt. — ^The  above  described  issues,  1-5  inclusive,  are  known  as  the 
Funded  Debt.  The  interest  is  included  in  the  permanent  or  fixed  annual  charge.  See 
also  page  82. 

(7)  Terminable  Annuities. — These  annuities  were  created  under  different  acts  dating 
from  the  time  of  George  IV. 

(8)  Unfunded  Debt. — All  debt,  except  the  Funded  Debt  and  the  Terminable  Annuities, 
is  technically  known  as  Unfimded  Debt. 

(9)  Ways  and  Means  Advances. — ^These  are  book  advances  made  by  the  Bank  of 
England  for  short  terms.     See  text,  page  36. 

(10)  3i%  War  Loan. — Original  issue,  £350  million.  Issued  in  Nov.,  1914,  at  95%. 
Inscribed  stock ;   or  bearer  bonds  in  denominations  of  £100,  £500  and  £1,000. 

(11)  4i%  War  Loan.— Original  issue,  £900,857,691.  Issued  21st  June  to  10th  July, 
1915,  partly  for  cash  at  par  and  partly  (say,  £289,797,921)  in  exchange  for  "  Consols  "  and 
3}%  war  loan.  The  greater  part  of  this  issue  has  been  exchanged  for  subsequent  war  issues. 
Inscribed  stock  ;  or  bonds  to  bearer  in  denominations  of  £100,  £200,  £500  £1,000  and  £5,000. 

(12)  5%  War  Loan.— Original  issue,  £2,075,814,114.  Issued  11th  Jan.  to  16th  Feb., 
1917,  at  95  for  cash  and  on  certain  terms  in  exchange  for  other  previous  issues.  Receivable 
on  certain  conditions  in  payment  of  death  duties.  Stock  and  bonds  and  the  dividends 
thereon  are  exempt  from  all  British  taxation  present  or  future  provided  they  are  in  the 
beneficial  ownership  of  a  person  who  is  neither  domiciled  nor  ordinarily  resident  in  the 
United  Kingdom.    Dividends  are  exempt,  without  regard  to  domicile,  if  the  owner  of  the 


184  ENGLISH   PUBLIC  FINANCE 

stock  or  bonds  is  not  ordinarily  a  resident  of  the  United  Kingdom.  Inscribed  stock ;  or 
bonds  to  bearer  in  denominations  of  £50,  £100,  £200,  £500,  £1,000  and  £5,000.  Interchange- 
able. 

(13)  4%  War  Loan.— Original  issue  £52,418,250.  Issued  simultaneously  with  (12)  at 
par  in  cash  and  on  certain  terms  in  exchange  for  previous  issues.  Interest  (dividends) 
exempt  from  British  Government  taxes  other  than  super  tax.  For  tax  exemption  in  hands 
of  foreigners  see  last  clause  (12).  Inscribed  stock  ;  or  bonds  to  bearer  in  denominations  of 
£50,  £100,  £200,  £500,  £1,000  and  £5,000.     Interchangeable. 

Etepreciation  Fund  :  The  holders  of  4%  and  5%  War  Loan  are  entitled  to  the  benefit 
of  a  Sinking  or  Depreciation  Fund  which  is  under  the  control  of  the  National  Debt  Commis- 
sioners. This  fund  is  applicable  to  the  purchase  and  cancellation  of  the  stock  and  bonds 
of  this  loan  whenever  the  market  price  of  the  4%  loan  is  below  100  or  of  the  5%  loan  below 
95.    See  item  34. 

(14)  National  War  Bonds. — First  Series. — Total  sales  about  £614  million.  Oflered  at 
par  1st  Oct.,  1917,  to  31st  March,  1918. 

Exempt  from  all  British  taxation  present  or  future  if  In  the  beneficial  ownership  of  a 
person  neither  domiciled  nor  ordinarily  resident  in  the  United  Kingdom.  Dividends  are 
exempt,  without  regard  to  domicile,  if  the  owner  of  the  stock  or  bonds  is  not  ordinarily 
a  resident  of  the  United  Kingdom.  Interest  on  the  4%  Bonds  exempt  from  British  income 
tax  other  than  super  tax.  Received  in  payment  of  death  duties,  excess  profits  duty  or 
munitions  exchequer  payments,  if  held  for  six  months  prior  to  the  date  of  presentation. 

Convertible  :  5%  Bonds  into  5%  War  Loan,  1929-47  (12)  at  the  rate  of  £100  5%  War 
Loan  for  each  £95  nominal  value  5%  National  War  Bonds  surrendered  ;  4%  Bonds  into 
4%  War  Loan  1929-42  (13)  at  the  rate  of  £110  War  Loan  for  each  £100  nominal  value 
National  War  Bonds  surrendered. 

Denominations,  £50,  £100,  £500,  £200,  £1,000  and  £5,000.  Issued  in  both  coupon  and 
registered  form  ;   also  in  registered  coupon  bonds. 

Payable  :  5%  Bonds  due  in  1922  at  102  ;  due  in  1924,  at  103  ;  due  in  1927,  at  105.  The 
4%  Bonds  are  payable  at  par. 

(15)  Second  Series  offered  at  par  1st  April,  1918,  to  30th  Sept.,  1918.  Total  sales  about 
£493  million.  Terms  same  as  first  series.  Payable  :  5%  Bonds  due  in  1923  at  102  ;  in 
1925,  at  103  ;   in  1928,  at  105.     4%  Bonds  payable  at  par. 

(16)  Third  Series.— ToUl  sales  about  £500  million.  Offered  30th  Sept.,  1918,  to  18th 
Jan.,  1919;  5%  bonds  at  par  and  4%  bonds  at  £101  IDs.  Payable:  5%  bonds  due  1st 
Sept.,  1923,  at  102,  1st  Sept.,  1925,  at  103,  1st  Sept.,  1928,  at  105  ;  4%  bonds  due  1st  Sept., 
1928,  at  100.     Other  terms  and  conditions,  same  as  first  stries. 

(17)  Fourth  Series.— Total  sales  about  £80  million.  Offered  31st  Jan.,  1919,  to  31st 
May,  1919;  5%  bonds  at  par;  4%  bonds  at  £101  10s.  Payable:  5%  bonds  1st  Feb., 
1924,  at  102,  1st  Feb.,  1929,  at  105  ;  4%  bonds  1st  Feb.,  1929,  at  100.  Terms  and  conditions 
same  as  first  series,  except  this  series  has  no  conversion  right  into  War  Loan. 

(18)  4%  Funding  Loan. — Original  issue  about  £409  million.  Offered  at  80  12th  June 
to  12th  July,  1919.  A  sum  equal  to  2^%  on  the  nominal  amount  of  the  loan  originally 
created  is  set  aside  semi-annually  and  any  balance  remaining  after  payment  of  interest  applied 
to  the  purchase  and  cancellation  of  bonds  if  obtainable  at  or  under  par.  See  item  34. 
Receivable  on  the  basis  of  80  in  payment  of  death  duties  if  held  by  the  deceased  for  "ix 
months  prior  to  death.  Exempt  from  taxation  in  the  hands  of  persons  neither  domiciled 
nor  ordinarily  resident  in  the  United  Kingdom.  The  interest  (dividends)  on  Iwnds  held  by 
persons  not  ordinarily  resident  in  the  United  Kingdom  will  be  paid  free  of  tax  without  regard 
to  domicile  of  owner.  Coupon  and  registered  (either  inscribed  stock  or  registered  certificate). 
Bearer  bonds  in  denominations  of  £50,  £100,  £200,  £500,  £1,000  and  £5,000. 

(19)  Victory  Bonds. — Original  issue  about  £360  million.  Offered  at  85  12th  June  to 
12th  July,  1919.  A  sum  equal  to  2i%  of  the  nominal  amount  of  bonds  originally  created 
is  set  aside  every  half  year,  and  after  payment  of  interest  the  balance  of  the  fund  is  applied 
to  the  redemption  of  bonds  at  par  by  lot  on  1st  Sept.,  of  each  year.  See  item  34.  Tax 
exemptions  as  in  (18).  Receivable  at  100  on  same  basis  as  (18)  in  payment  of  death  duties. 
Bearer  and  registered  Bonds,  but  interest  in  all  cases  payable  by  means  of  Coupons  attached 
to  bonds. 

(20)  ExciiEoUER  Bonds. — First  introduced  by  Mr.  Gladstone  in  1853.  At  present  there 
are  six  series  of  these  bonds  outstanding  ;  the  five  series  described  in  the  table  and  the  new 
series  described  on  page  193.  The  bonds  of  all  issues  are  p  lyable  to  bearer  and  are  in  denomina- 
tions of  £50,  £100,  £200,  £500,  £1,000  and  £5,000  except  there  are  no  £200  bonds  in  the  3% 
issue  of  28th  Jan.,  1920.  The  Exchequer  Bonds  may  be  registered  either  as  inscribed  stock 
or  registered  certificate.  The  5%  issue  of  1920  andthe5's  of  1922  are  receivable  in  payment 
of  death  duties,  the  5's  of  1922  will  also  be  received  in  payment  of  excess  profit  duties  and 
munitions  exchequer  payments  on  the  same  conditions  as  those  attached  to  the  National 
War  Bonds.    The  holders  of  5J%  issue  due  1925  may  give  notice  during  the  month  of  Jan. 


NATIONAL   DEBT  185 

in  any  of  the  years  1921,  1922  or  1923,  requiring  repayment  of  the  bonds  at  par  on  the 
1st  of  Feb.  in  the  year  next  succeeding  that  in  which  such  notice  is  given.  Under  no  circum- 
stances may  notice  once  given  be  subsequently  withdrawn.  Tax  provisions  all  issues,  except 
the  last,  concerning  which  there  appears  to  be  no  exemption,  same  as  item  (18). 

(21)  Treasury  Bills. — On  14th  April,  1915,  a  scheme  was  put  into  operation  under 
which  the  Bank  of  England  was  prepared  to  receive  applications  daily  for  Treasury  bills 
to  mature  at  various  dates  up  to  twelve  months  after  date  of  issue,  but  the  sale  of  such 
bills  was  suspended  on  3rd  Jan.,  1917.  On  30th  March,  1917,  the  sale  of  bills  by  tender 
was  resumed,  but  the  last  issue  under  this  system  was  made  on  I5th  June,  1917,  and  was 
repaid  15th  June,  1918,  while  on  18th  June,  1917,  the  method  of  daily  sales  at  fixed  rates 
was  reverted  to,  and  was  continued  until  30th  May,  1919,  when  sales  were  suspended  for  some 
weeks.  On  15th  July,  1919,  bills  were  again  placed  on  sale  and  are  now  (May,  1920)  issued 
with  a  currency  of  three  months.     See  also  pages  75  and  193  and  Index. 

(22)  War  Savings  Certificates. — The  issue  of  these  Certificates  was  commenced  Feb., 
1916,  at  the  rate  of  15s.  6d.  for  every £1  certificate,  repayable  at  par  free  of  income  tax  in  5 
years  from  dates  of  issue.    See  also  page  21. 

(23)  Other  Capital  Liabilities. — These  comprise  sundry  liabilities  under  the  Telegraph 
and  Telephone  Acts,  Public  Works  Acts,  Mi'itary  Works  Acts,  and  several  similar  acts. 

(24)  Debt  to  the  United  States  Government. — The  British  Finance  Accounts  do 
not  give  details  in  regard  to  this  indebtedness.  The  report  of  the  Secretary'  of  Treasury 
of  the  United  States  presented  to  Congress  on  20th  Nov.,  1919, states  that  the  total  advances 
of  the  British  Government  to  15th  Nov.,  1920  aggregated  $4,277,000,000.  A  letter  of 
the  Secretary  of  the  Treasury  to  the  Senate  dated  13th  March,  1920,  indicates  repayments 
of  $64,164,000.     The  accrued  unpaid  interest  to  10th  March  was  reported  to  be  $21 1,828,890. 

(25)  Anglo-French  Loan. — This  loan  for  $500,000,000  offered  in  New  York,  14th  Oct., 
1915,  at  98.  It  is  a  joint  and  several  obligation  of  the  Governments  of  the  United  Kingdom 
of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  and  the  French  Republic.  Principal  and  interest  are  payable 
in  New  York  City,  in  United  States  gold  coin  without  deduction  for  any  present  or  future 
British  or  French  taxes.  Coupon  Bonds  in  denominations  of  $100,  $500  and  $1,000  may 
be  registered  as  to  principal  Registered  Bonds  in  denominations  of  $1,000,  $10  000  and 
$50,000  and  authorized  multiples.  Coupon  and  registered  bonds  interchangeable.  Con- 
vertible at  the  option  of  the  holder  on  any  date  not  later  than  15th  April,  1920,  or  (provided 
that  notice  be  given  not  later  than  15th  Apni,  1920)  at  maturity  par  for  pai  into  14-25  year 
joint  and  several  4i%  bonds  of  the  Governments  of  the  United  Kingdom  of  Great  Britain 
and  Ireland  and  the  French  Republic.  Such  4^%  bonds  will  be  payab'e  principal  and 
intere-t  n  United  States  gold  coin  in  New  York  City  free  from  deduction  for  any  present 
or  future  British  or  French  taxes.  They  will  mature  15th  Oct.,  1940,  but  will  be  re- 
deemable at  par  and  accrued  interest  in  whole  or  in  part  on  any  interest  date  not  earlier 
than  15th  Oct.,  1930,  upon  3  months  notice. 

(26)  Secured  Dollar  Notes. — Part  of  an  original  issue  of  $150,000,000  made  in  New  York, 
1st  Nov.,  1916,  principal  and  interest  payable  in  New  Yorkin  United  State-gold  coinoratthe 
option  of  the  holder  in  London  in  sterling  at  the  fixed  rate  of  $4865  to  the  pound.  Free 
of  any  British  taxes  present  or  future.  Redeemab'e  on  30  days  notice  from  1st  Nov.,  1919, 
to  31st  Oct.,  1920,  at  102,  and  interest,  and  from  1st  Nov.,  1920  to  31st  Oct.,  1921,  at  101 
and  interest.  Secured  by  pi  dge  with  the  Guaranty  Trust  Company  of  New  York  of  securities 
approved  by  Messrs.  J.  P.  Morgan  &  Co.  having  a  market  value  of  20%  over  the  par  value 
of  the  notes  outstanding.  The  Government  may  sell  the  collateral  at  any  time  and  apply 
the  proceeds  of  sale  to  the  retirement  of  the  notes  by  purchase  or  redemption  by  lot. 

(27)  3-Year  Convertible  Notes. — Issued  in  New  York,  23rd  Oct.,  1919,  at  98  and 
interest.  Offered  in  conjunction  with  10-year  convertible  bends  (28)  $250,000  000  in  aU. 
Denominations  $100,  $500,  and  $1,000.  Interest  and  principal  payable  in  New  York  in 
United  States  gold  coin,  without  deduction  for  any  British  taxes  present  or  future.  Con- 
vertible at  the  option  of  the  holder  at  par  and  interest  into  National  War  5%  Bonds  fourth 
series  (17),  sterling  exchange  being  computed  for  the  purpose  of  conversion  at  the  fixed 
rate  of  $4'30  to  the  pound.  Conversion  may  be  made  at  any  time  pr'  to  21st  Nov.,  1922, 
notice  to  be  given  prior  to  1st  Sept.  1922,  of  intention  to  convert.  The  converting  note 
holder  wi"  be  entitled  to  receive  £232  12s.  principal  amount  of  such  National  War  Bonds 
for  $1,000  of  principal  amount  notes  surrendered. 

(28)  10- Year  Convertible  Gold  Bonds —Offered  in  New  York  with  (27)  23rd  Oct., 
at  96i  and  interest.  Principal  and  interest  payable  in  New  York  'n  United  States  gold 
coin,  free  of  any  British  taxes  present  or  future.  Coupon  bonds  in  denominations  of  $100, 
$500,  $1,000,  registered  as  to  principal.  Convertible  at  any  time  prior  to  1st  Feb.,  1929. 
For  terms  and  conditions  see  above.  No.  26. 

(29)  20- Year  Gold  Bonds. — Issued  1st  Feb.,  1919,  in  exchange  for  2-year  secured  notes 
of  the  United  K  ngdom  which  matured  on  that  date.  Principal  and  interest  payable  in 
New  York,  in  United  States  gold  coin  or  in  London  at  the  fixed  rate  of  $4,865,  free  of  British 
taxes,  present  or  future.    Denominations,  coupon  bonds,  $100,  $500  and  $1,000,  principal 


186  ENGLISH  PUBLIC  FINANCE 


registerable.     Registered  bonds  $1,000,  $5,000  and  $10,000,  coupon  and  registered  bonds 
interchangeable. 

(30)  Other  Debt  Created  Ukder  War  Loan  Act. — "  Other  debt  is  taken  to  include 
all  borrowings  outside  this  country,  with  the  exception  of  the  first  American  Loan  raised 
in  Nov.,  1916,  under  the  American  Loan  Act."  (The  Anglo-French  5's)  (Economist,  3rd  April, 
1920.)  In  the  table  the  amount  due  in  and  to  the  United  States  has  been  segregated  with 
the  possible  exception  of  around  £12  million  due  for  Treasury  Bills  sold  in  New  York.  Of 
the  sum  remaining  the  Monthly  Review  for  March,  1920,  of  the  London  Joint  City  &  Midland 
Bank  estimates  approximately  £150  million  to  be  due  to  other  foreign  countries — including 
Argentina,  Uruguay,  Japan  and  other  neutrals  ;  the  balance  probably  represents  amounts 
due  to  the  Dominions. 

(31)  Guaranteed  Loans. — Any  liability  In  connection  with  these  loans  is  apparently 
remote  as  all  the  foreign  loans  are  a  charge  upon  certain  revenues  of  the  nations  whose  bonds 
are  guaranteed.  The  local  loans  are  secured  by  the  assets  of  the  Local  Loan  Funds  which 
are  supported  by  local  taxation.  The  Irish  Land  Purchase  Bonds  are  secured  by  the  Irish 
Land  Purchase  Funds. 

TRANSFER   REGULATIONS. 

(32)  Transfer  and  Other  Regulations. — The  Bank  of  England  and  the  Bank  of  Ireland 
act  as  fiscal  and  transfer  agents  for  the  British  Government  debt. 

Transfers. — ^Transfers  of  Government  securities  can  be  made  without  charge  from  the  boolcs 
of  the  Bank  of  England  to  the  books  of  the  Bank  of  Ireland  or  vice  versa.  Transfer  days, 
Monday  to  Friday,  inclusive,  free  of  charge  ;  Saturday  upon  the  payment  of  a  fee  of  2s.  6d. 

Stocks  (Registered  bonds,  American  parlance)  are  transferred  in  multiples  of  a  penny 
(oi  on  the  books  of  the  Bank,  in  which  case  the  owner  has  no  documentary  evidence  of 
ownership  (such  stock  is  known  as  inscribed  stock)  or  (6)  by  deed  in  which  case  the  owner 
receives  a  certificate  by  the  Bank  of  England  in  the  following  form  :  "  This  is  to  Certify  that 
(blank)  is  the  registered  proprietor  of  (blank  amount)  registered  (here  follows  the  title  of  the 
Loan.)"  Bearer  Coupon  Bonds  are  obtainable  in  exchange  for  mscribcd  stock  or  stock 
transferred  by  deed,  in  the  case  of  most  issues.  Registered  Coupon  Bonds  are  issued  in  the 
same  denominations  as  Bearer  Bonds.  A  Certificate  of  ownership  similar  to  (h)  above  is 
issued  to  which  Coupons  for  interest  are  attached.  Each  Registered  Coupon  Bond  is 
transferable  by  deed  but  only  in  its  entire  amount. 

Dividends. — Cheques  for  dividends  on  inscribed  and  registered  stocks  are  mailed  to  the 
owner. 

All  business  In  regard  to  transfers  must  be  conducted  at  the  Bank  of  England  or  the 
Bank  of  Ireland  in  person  or  through  a  banker  or  other  agent.  The  banks  will  not  carry 
out  any  of  these  operations  by  correspondence. 

SINKING   AND    DEPRECIATION    FUNDS. 

Sinking  Funds. — Old  Sinking  Fund  (38  and  39  Vict.)  consisting  of  the  surplus,  if  any, 
of  income  over  expenditure  for  any  year  which  the  Treasury  in  the  course  of  the 
next  financial  year  shall  cause  to  be  issued  out  of  the  Consolidated  Fund,  or  the  growing 
produce  thereof,  at  such  times  during  that  year  as  they  may  from  time  to  time  direct.  Ihe 
Old  Sinking  Fund  is  to  be  issued  to  the  National  Debt  Commissioners  and  applied  by  them 
in  the  same  manner  as  the  New  Sinking  Fund,  except  that  it  may  be  employed  in  paying 
ofi  advances  made  by  the  Bank  of  England  or  the  Bank  of  Ireland  in  pursuance  of  Section 
12  of  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Act,  1866,  but  not  in  paying  off  any  loan  borrowed  under 
any  Act  to  meet  ways  and  means. 

New  Sinking  Fund  (38  and  39  Vict.)  consisting  of  such  portion  of  the  permanent  annual 
charge  for  the  National  Debt  as  in  any  financial  year  not  required  for  the  purpose  of  paying 
the  annual  charges.  This  is  to  be  Issued  from  time  to  time  to  the  National  Debt  Commis- 
sioners and  be  applied  by  them,  within  six  months  after  the  date  of  issue  thereof,  in  purchasing, 
redeeming,  or  paying  off  any  one  or  more  of  the  following  descriptions  of  debt — namely, 
Annuities  (perpetual  or  terminable)  charged  on  the  Consolidated  Fund,  and  Exchequer 
Bonds  and  Exchequer  Bills  (whether  held  by  the  public  or  on  account  of  the  Exchequer, 
or  sent  Into  the  Bank  of  England  for  payment)  ;  but  the  New  Sinking  Fund  is  not  to  be  applied 
in  paying  off  any  advances  made  by  the  Bank  of  England  or  the  Bank  of  Ireland  in  pursuance 
of  Section  12  of  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Act,  1866,  or  in  paying  off  any  loan  borrowed 
under  any  Act  to  meet  ways  and  means.     (See  Application  of  Sinking  Funds,  below.) 

An  Annuity  of  £15,547  created  under  the  National  Debt  (Conversion  of  Stock)  Act,  1884, 
to  extinguish  the  increase  in  the  nominal  capital  amount  of  the  National  Debt  due  to  conver- 
sion of  3%  Stock  into  2}  and  21%  Stock,  and  expiring  in  1934. 

Application  of  Sinking  Funds. — The  Finance  Act,  1915,  makes  Sections  3  and  4  of  the 
Sinking  Fund  Act,  1875  (which  relate  to  the  application  of  the  Old  and  New  Sinking  Funds), 


NATIONAL   DEBT  187 

applicable  to  any  securities  issued  under  the  War  Loan  Act,  19M,  or  any  Act  extending 
or  amending  that  Act  or  any  other  enactment  autboriring  money  to  be  borrowed  for  the 
purpose  of  the  present  war  in  like  manner  as  they  apply  to  annuities  charged  on  the 
Consolidated  Fund. 

Depreciation  Fund  for  4%  and  5%  War  Loans.— [Items  12  and  13.)  The  foUowinR 
regulations  have  been  made  by  the  Treasury  respecting  the  Depreciation  Fund  for  4%  and 
5%  War  Loan.  Under  Section  32  of  the  Finance  Act,  1917  :  (1)  There  shall  be  established 
a  fund  to  be  known  as  the  "  Depreciation  Fund,"  under  the  control  of  the  National  Debt 
Commissioners.  (2)  The  following  sums  shall  be  paid  to  the  fund  from  time  to  time  under 
the  direction  of  the  Treasury  :  (a)  In  respect  of  the  six  months  from  17th  Feb.,  1917,  to 
16th  August,  1917,  an  amount  equal  to  six-eighths  of  1%  of  the  total  nominal  value  of  the 
Stock  and  Bonds  of  the  4%  War  Loan,  1929-1942,  and  the  5%  War  Loan,  1929-1947, 
originally  created  ;  (6)  in  respect  of  each  succeeding  month  an  amount  equal  to  one-eighth 
of  1%  of  the  total  nominal  value  of  the  said  Stock  and  Bonds  ;  provided  that  no  payTnent 
shall  be  made  to  the  fund  in  respect  of  any  period  during  which  the  unexpended  balance 
of  the  fund  amounts  to  £10,000,000.  (3)  The  moneys  standing  to  the  credit  of  the  Depreci- 
ation Fund  shall  be  applied  from  time  to  time  by  the  National  Debt  Commissioners  in  the 
purchase  of  Stock  or  Bonds  of  4%  War  Loan,  1929-1942,  or  5%  War  Loan,  1929-1947, 
whenever  the  market  price  of  the  Stock  and  Bonds  of  these  issues  is  below  the  respective 
issue  prices — viz.,  £100  and  £95.  (4)  The  Stock  and  Bonds  bought  on  behalf  of  the  Depreci- 
ation Fund  shall  be  cancelled  in  the  same  manner  as  Stock  or  Bonds  bought  for  the  Old 
and  New  Sinking  Funds.  (5)  The  National  Debt  Commissioners  shall,  out  of  moneys 
standing  to  the  credit  of  the  Depreciation  Fund,  purchase  for  that  fund  any  Stock  or  Bonds 
of  the  4%  War  Loan,  1929-1942,  or  the  5%  War  Loan,  1929-1947,  purchased  out  of  funds 
standing  to  the  credit  of  any  Government  Account  between  the  17th  Feb.,  1917,  and  the 
passing  of  the  Finance  Act,  1917,  in  anticipation  of  the  establishment  of  the  Depreciation 
Fund.  (6)  Any  sums  tanding  to  the  credit  of  the  fund,  and  not  required  for  the  immediate 
purchase  of  such  Stock  or  Bonds  as  aforesaid,  may  be  invested  by  the  National  Debt  Commis- 
sioners in  Treasury  Bills,  or  in  advances  to  the  Treasury  oi  sums  which  the  Treasury  may 
borrow  for  the  purpose  of  raising  any  sum  which  they  arc  authorized  to  issue  out  of  the 
Consolidated  Fund  under  any  Consolidated  Fund  Act  or  Appropriation  Act.  (Up  to  the 
15th  March,  1919,  the  amount  issued  out  of  the  Exchequer  for  the  Depreciation  Fund  was 
£62,180,513.) 

Sinking  Fund  for  4%  Funding  Loan  and  Victory  Bonds. — (Items  18  and  19.)  His 
Majesty's  Government  undertake  to  set  aside  at  the  close  of  each  half-year  a  sum  equal 
to  2i%  on  the  nominal  amount  of  the  Loan  and  Bonds  originally  created.  After  deducting 
therefrom  the  amount  required  for  payment  of  interest  on  the  Loan  for  the  half-year,  the 
balance  of  the  sum  so  set  aside  will  be  carried  to  a  Sinking  Fimd  which  will  be  applied  as 
follows — 

In  the  case  of  the  Funding  Loan  ;  during  the  succeeding  half-year  to  the  purchase  of  the 
Loan  for  cancellation  if  the  price  is  at  or  under  par ;  when  the  price  is  above  par  it  will  be 
either  so  applied  or  otherwise  invested  under  the  control  of  His  Majesty's  Treasury.  Any 
outstanding  balance  of  the  Loan  not  previously  redeemed  will  be  repaid  at  par  on  1st  May, 
1990,  but  His  Majesty's  Government  reserve  to  themselves  the  right,  on  giving  three  calendar 
months  notice  in  the  London  Gatette,  to  redeem  at  par  at  any  time  on  or  after  1st  May,  any 
outstanding  balance  of  the  Loan  not  previously  purchased  and  cancelled  by  the  operation 
of  the  Sinking  Fund. 

In  the  case  of  the  Victory  Bonds  ;  by  annual  drawings  to  the  redemption  of  the  Bonds 
at  par  (including  Bonds  which  have  been  surrendered  to  the  Commissioners  of  Inland  Revenue 
for  death  duties  as  hereinafter  provided),  the  Bonds  to  be  redeemed  in  each  year  detemined 
by  lot  and  paid  off  on  1st  Sept.  in  such  year  in  accordance  with  regulations  made  by  the 
Treasury.  The  numbers  of  the  Bonds  drawn  for  redemption  on  each  occasion  will  be  adver- 
tised in  the  London  Ga-.ette  not  less  than  two  months  prior  to  the  date  of  redemption. 
Interest  on  Bonds  drawn  for  repayment  will  cease  from  the  date  on  which  the  Bonds  becom* 
repayable.    The  first  drawing  will  be  that  for  the  Bonds  to  be  redeemed  on  1st  Sept.,  1920. 

AUTHORITIES. 

The  sources  from  which  the  above  tables  and  notes  have  been  compiled  are  Finance 
Accounts  for  1919-20,  the  Stock  Exchange  (London)  Daily  Official  List,  official  circulars  so  far 
as  obtainable,  the  Stock  Exchange  Official  Intelligence,  Vol.  38 — for  1920,  The  Economist, 
and  The  Bankers  Magasine  (London). 


188 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


QUOTATIONS. 

Consols  and  Bank  of  England  Stock, 

1697-1919. 

For  closing  years  of  historical  periods  and  yearly  from  1857. 


Consols. 

Bank  of 

ENGLAND 

Year. 

Price. 

Average  (A)  Yield. 

Price. 

High. 

Month. 

Low. 

Month. 

Price. 

% 

High. 

Low. 

1697 

(a)   97 

79 

(e)  88.0 

5.7 

(i)   98 

514 

1701 

(a)   79 

57 

(«)  68.0 

7.3 

(/)  123 

1034 

1714 

(?)   ^=* 

78} 

(e)    86.2 

5.8 

(m)   133} 

116i 

1739 

(6)  105 

Jan. 

97 

Nov. 

(/)  101.9 

3.3 

(»)  144 

134 

1749 

102 

Oct. 

91 

Feb. 

97.6 

3.1 

140 

127 

1755 

101 

Jan. 

90 

Oct. 

94.5 

3.2 

131 

120 

1766 

90 

Jan. 

87 

Feb. 

88.5 

3.4 

140 

134 

1775 

90 

Jan. 

87 

July 

89.6 

3.3 

146 

140 

1785 

71 

Dec. 

55 

Feb. 

59.7 

5.0 

130 

112 

1792 

(c)      96 

Mar. 

76 

Dec. 

(g)  90.0 

(g)  3.3 

216 

175 

1802 

76 

Apr. 

68 

Jan. 

70.9 

4.2 

195 

180 

1817 

84i 

Dec. 

62 

Jan. 

75.3 

4.0 

(o)  294 

220 

1833 

91i 

June 

84} 

Jan. 

{h)    87.7 

3.4 

213i 

190 

1842 

97i 

Dec. 

88J 

Jan. 

(t)  92.0 

3.3 

173 

165 

1847 

93i 

Jan. 

78} 

Oct. 

87.2 

3.4 

206J 

180 

1854 

95J 

Sept. 

85J 

Mar. 

U)     9'-9 

3.3 

221 

2044 

1857 

94i 

Jan. 

86i 

Oct. 

91.9 

3.3 

222 

209 

1858 

981 

Oct. 

94i 

Jan. 

96.9 

3.1 

230 

217 

1859 

971 

Dec. 

88} 

Apr. 

95.1 

3.1 

231 

215 

1860 

95J 

Jan. 

92} 

Oct. 

94.0 

3.2 

235i 

225 

1861 

94i 

Nov. 

89i 

July 

91.5 

3.3 

241 

226i 

1862 

94J 

July 

914 

Jan. 

93.0 

3,2 

(/>)  244 

232^ 

1863 

94 

May 

90 

Dec. 

92.6 

3.2 

240 

232 

1864 

92 

May 

874 

Sept. 

90.1 

3.3 

244 

234 

1865 

91i 

June 

86} 

Dec. 

89.5 

3.3 

250 

238} 

1866 

90J 

Dec. 

84f 

May 

88.0 

3.4 

253 

240 

1867 

96i 

June 

89i 

Apr. 

93.0 

3.2 

264 

239 

1868 

96i 

May 

91} 

Jan. 

93.9 

3.2 

251 

240 

1869 

94i 

June 

91} 

May 

92.9 

3.3 

246 

235 

1870 

94 1 

May 

884 

Aug. 

92.5 

3.3 

1871 

94 

July 

911 

Dec. 

92.7 

3.3 

1872 

93i 

May 

914 

Dec. 

92.5 

3.3 

1873 

94 

May 

91} 

Dec. 

92.5 

3.3 

1874 

931 

May 

91} 

Dec. 

92.5 

3.3 

(r)  261 

2494 

1875 

95} 

Nov. 

914 

Jan. 

93.7 

3.2 

262 

251 

1876 

97i 

July 

93} 

Dec. 

95.0 

3.2 

260 

248 

1877 

97J 

Nov. 

93 

May 

95.4 

3.1 

267 

255 

1878 

98 

June 

93} 

Oct. 

95.2 

3.1 

263 

249 

1879 

991 

Apr. 

944 

Jan. 

97.5 

3.1 

271 

249 

1880 

100} 

Nov. 

97} 

Sept. 

98.4 

3.0 

280 

269 

1881 

103 

May 

98} 

Jan. 

100.0 

3.0 

299 

278 

1882 

102i 

May 

99 

Jan. 

100.5 

3.0 

291 

284 

1883 

102} 

Feb. 

99} 

July 

101.4 

2.9 

.302 

288 

1884 

102} 

Apr. 

984 

Dec. 

lOI.O 

2.9 

312 

294 

1885 

101| 

May 

9!« 

Apr. 

99.3 

3.0 

309 

2894 

1886 

102  J 

Nov. 

99} 

Jan. 

100.8 

3.0 

299 

291 

1887 

103} 

May 

994 

Feb. 

101.8 

2.9 

3084 

294 

1888 

103  J 

Mar. 

984 

Dec. 

lOI.O 

2.9 

332 

303 

1889 

99} 

Jan. 

96} 

Sept. 

98.0 

2.8 

346 

320 

1890 

98} 

May 

931 

Nov. 

96.3 

2.8 

3404 

327 

1891 

97i 

Jan. 

94} 

June 

95.7 

2.9 

343 

323 

1892 

96i 

Dec. 

93} 

Jan. 

96.7 

2.8 

344 

325 

1893 

98} 

June 

951 

Sept. 

98.5 

2.8 

344 

327 

1894 

1021 

Dec. 

974 

Jan. 

101.1 

2.7 

(s)  343 

325 

1895 

108  J 

Sept. 
July 

103} 

Jan. 

106.2 

2.6 

3384 

322 

1896 

113} 

1054 

Jan. 

110.7 

2.5 

336 

322 

NATIONAL   DEBT 


189 


QVOTATIO'^S— Continued. 

Consols  and  Bank  of  England  Stock, 

1697-1919. 

For  closing  years  of  historical  periods  and  yearly  from  1857 


Consols. 

Bank  of  E 

NGLAND. 

Year 

Price 

Average  {k)  Yield. 

Pric 

e 

High. 

Month. 

Low. 

Month. 

Price. 

% 

High. 

Low. 

1897 

U3i 

May 

110} 

Mar. 

112.4 

2.4 

328 

325 

1898 

1131 

Jan. 

106} 

Oct. 

110.9 

2.5 

351J 

326 

1899 

lllj 

Jan. 

97} 

Dec. 

106.9 

2.6 

(f)  361} 

325 

1900 

103i 

June 

96} 

Dec. 

99.6 

2.7 

349 

326 

1901 

97J 

Feb. 

91 

July 

94.2 

2.9 

342 

320 

1902 

97J 

June 

92} 

Dec. 

94.4 

2.9 

326} 

323} 

1903 

93  4 

Apr. 

86} 

Apr. 

90.7 

2.7 

331} 

311 

1904 

{d)      91} 

June 

85 

Mar. 

88.2 

2.8 

316 

295} 

1905 

91|S 

Mar. 

sn 

Jan. 

89.8 

2,8 

308 

291} 

1906 

91J 

Apr. 

85t"b 

Oct. 

88.3 

2.8 

301 

268 

1907 

87  ,^ 

Feb. 

80} 

Aug. 

84.1 

2.9 

288} 

255 

1908 

88^ 

Mar. 

83  i"^ 

Dec. 

86.1 

2.9 

(«)  285 

258* 

1909 

86 

Apr. 

82^ 

Oct. 

84.0 

3.0 

279 

256" 

1910 

83} 

Jan. 

78} 

Dec. 

81.0 

3.1 

272 

250 

1911 

82 ,3,. 

Apr. 

76} 

Sept. 

(t)  79.3 

3.1 

263} 

242} 

1912 

79,^, 

Feb. 

72i 

Oct. 

76.1 

3.3 

251 

234 

1913 

75}" 

Mar. 

71 

Dec. 

73^i 

3.4 

251 

224} 

1914 

77}', 

Feb. 

69i 

July 

741? 

3.3 

256 

234 

1915 

68} 

Jan. 

57 

Nov. 

65.5 

4.1 

249} 

230 

1916 

61} 

June 

53} 

Dec. 

58.0 

4.2 

230} 

194} 

1917 

56} 

Oct. 

51 

Feb. 

(e)  54.0 

4.6 

205 

190 

1918 

63i 

Oct. 

53J 

Mar. 

58.2 

4.3 

226 

191} 

1919 

60 

Jan. 

49} 

Sept. 

55.0 

4.5 

(u)    224} 

186} 

(a)  These  quotations  are  not  for  Government  Stock  but  for  the  stock  of  the  "  Million 
Bank,"  an  investment  trust  whose  funds  were  invested  in  Government  stocks.  The 
quotations  probably  give  a  better  idea  of  the  true  market  than  would  quotations  for  Govern- 
ment annuities.  The  first  quotation  is  for  1700,  the  first  year  in  which  the  Million  Bank 
stock  was  quoted.  The  dividends  paid  by  the  Million  Bank  in  these  years  were  at  the  rate 
of  5%.     Scott,  W.  R.,  Vol.  II.     See  Authorities. 

(6)  (1739-1785)  Rogers,  J.  E.  T.     History  of  Agriculture  and  Prices,  Vol.  VII,  Part  II. 

(c)   (1792-1903)  Mabson— The  Statist's  History  of  the  Public  Debt. 

\d)  (1904-1919)   Investors'  Monthly  Manual. 

(e)  Average  of  high  and  low  only. 

(/)  (1739-1785)  Average  of  daily  prices  as  recorded  in  Rogers  J.  E.  T.,  History  of 
Agriculture  and  Prices,  Vol.  VII,  Part  II. 

(g)  (1792-1817)  Average  of  the  mean  of  the  monthly  high  and  low  prices.  Silberling, 
N.  J.  in  Harvard  Review  of  Economic  Statistics,  Oct.,  1919. 

(h)  Van  Sommers,  James.     Tables,  London,  1848. 

(»)  (1842-1847)  (1911-1916)  Statistical  Abstract  for  United  Kingdom  Average  monthly 
price. 

ij)  (1854-1910)  Average  and  yield.  Williams,  T  T.,  Jouma'  of  Royal  Statistical  Society 
March,  1912. 

(ft)  Except  where  otherwise  noted  the  yield  is  obtained  by  dividing  the  average  yearly 
price  into  the  rate  of  interest.  This  rate  was  3%  from  1739  to  5th  April,  1889,  then  2}% 
to  6th  April,  1903,  and  since  then  2}%. 

(1)    (1697-1701)  Scott,  W.  R.,  Vol.  II.     See  Authorities. 

(»i)  (1714)  Rogers,  J.  E.  T.,  History  of  Agriculture  and  Prices,  Vol.  VII,  Part  IL 

(n)  (1739-1802)  Sinclair,  Vol.  II.     See  Authorities. 

(o)  (1817-1861)  Francis,  John — History  of  Bank  of  England — Its  Times  and  Traditions. 

ip)  (1862-1869)  Thorn's  Irish  Almanac  and  Official  Directory  of  the  United  Kingdom 
of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland. 

(f)   (1874-1893)  (1899-1907)   Investors'  Monthly  Manual. 

(s)   (1894-1898)  Stock  Exchange  Ol/icial  Intelligence. 

{I)    (19081918)  Mathieson's  Handbook  for  Investors,  1919. 

(«)  (1919)    Investors'  Monthly  Manual. 

(u)  High  and  low  prices.  The  months  given  for  the  high  and  low  prices  of  the  year  are 
those  in  which  the  price  first  occurred.  In  some  years  these  same  prices  were  reached 
several  times. 


190 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


QUOTATIONS. 

LONDON   STOCK   EXCHANGE. 

British  Funds. 


Calendar  Years. 

1910  !  1911  j 1912 

1913 

191 

1915    1916 

1917  j 1918 

1919 

Name. 
2J%     (Goschen)     1923 

Money.      (Int.    Jan., 

Apr.,  July,  Oct.)       . 
2i     (Childere)     (Int. 

Jan.,  Apr.,  Ju!.,Oct.) 
21%  Money  (Int.  Jan., 

Apr.,  July.  Oct.) 
31%    War    Loan,    red. 

1925-28.      (Int.  Mar., 

H 
L 
H 

L 
H 

L 

H 
L 

H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 

H 
L 
H 
L 
H 
L 

831 

781 

91i 

87 

811 

761 

82.3, 

761 

89 

80} 

801 

741 

79,1, 

721 

821 

73} 

76} 

701 

75» 

71 

7Hi 

741 

731 

671 

77  K', 

691 

80} 

741 

74} 

671 

68} 

57 

761 

59} 

65} 

54 

951 
891 

99|g 
961 

61} 
56} 
621 
531 
591 
50 

90} 
83 

971s 
921 

66i      631 
501   i  531 
56  f/  611 
531      S3i 
531      59} 
48     j  501 

871      891^ 

60 

49} 

601 

501 

561 

461 

891 

Sept.) 

1 

83,»B 
1011 

85 
lOU 

841 

41%    War    Loan,    red. 
1925-45       (Int.  June, 

1001 

Dec.) 

891      98} 

961     961 
921      92} 

831 

5%      War    Loan,    red. 
1929-47.     (Int.  June, 

96  ?« 

Dec.) 

1 

89  [it 

4%  War  Lo.  n,  red.  1929- 

1 

1031 
991 

103 

42.     (Int.  Apr.,  Oct.) 

i 

. 

98} 

4%    Funding    Loan 
1960-90.      (Int.  May, 

781 

Nov.) 

74 

4%  Victory  Bonds 

851 

(Mar.,  Sept.)      . 

National  War  Bonds. 

First  Series. 
S%   (Apr.,   Oct.),   Oct., 
1922 

79| 

101 

97 

5%    (Apr.,   Oct.)    Oct., 

1011 

1924 

961 

5%    (Apr.    Oct.),   Oct., 
1927 

:::::::::: 

1001 

951 

4%   (Apr.,  Oct.),   Oct., 
1927 

100} 

971 

Second  Series 
5%    (Apr.,  Oct.),   Apr., 

1001 

1923 

96 

5%   (Apr.     Oct.),   Apr., 

lOOf 

1925 

:::::i:::;; 

961 

5%   (Apr.,  Oct.),  Apr., 

1001 

1928 

951 

4%   (Apr.,  Oct.),   Apr., 

1001 

1928 

971 

Third  Series. 
5%  (Mar.,  Sept.),  Sept., 

1001 

1923 

951 

5%  (Mar.,  Sept.),  Sept., 

100} 

1925 

96. 
100 

5%  (Mar.,  Sept.),  Sept., 
1928 

95} 

4%  (Mar.,  Sept.)  Sept., 

100 
97 

1928 

Fourth  Series. 
6%  (Feb.,  Aug ),  Feb., 

1001 

1924 

451 

5%  (Feb.,  Aug.),  Feb., 

100} 

1929 

971 

4%  (Feb.,  Aug.).  Feb., 

tool 

97 

NATIONAL    DEBT 


191 


QUOTATIONS  LONDON  STOCK  EXCHANGE  [Continued). 
British  Funds. 


Calendar  Years. 


1910  1 1911  I  1912  1913  1914  1915  1916  j  1917  ;  1918  1919 


Name. 

Exchequer  Bokds. 

3%    Jan.,    1930.      (Int. 

Jan.,  Apr. ,  July,  Oct ) 

3%  Jan..  1930.      (Int. 

Jan.,  July) 
5%  Dec,  1920.     (June, 

Dec.) 
5%    Oct.,    1921.      (Int. 

April,  Oct.) 
5%  1919-22,  Apr.,  1922. 

(April,  Oct.)      . 
6%  Feb.,  1920.      (Feb., 

Aug.) 
2i%   Guaranteed,   1933 
(issued  under  Irish 
Land  Act).  (Int.  Jan., 
July)        . 
2i%    Guaranteed    1921 

(Int.,  Jan.,  July) 

3%  Guaranteed   red.,  2 

Dec,  1939.  (Int.  Jan., 

July)        . 

3%  Local  Loans,  1912. 

(Int.   Jan.,   Apr.    July, 

Oct.) 

3%    Met.    Poiice   Deb., 

1920.  (Int.  Jan.,  July) 

3%  Egyptian  Guar.   (Int 

Mar.,  Sept.)    1951      . 

2i%  Greek  Gua.  Loans 

(Int.  Apr.,  Oct.),  1898 

3%    Mauritius,    1940 

(Int.  Jan.,  July) 
.5J%  Soudan  Govt.Gtd. 
Bds.  (Int.  May,  Nov.) 
3%   Transvaal        Gua. 
1923-53  Money.    (Int. 
May,  Nov.) 
3%  Transvaal  Gua.  red. 
1st  July,  1958.    (Int. 
Jan.,  July) 
4%  Turkish  Gua.    (Int. 

Feb.,  Aug.)  1855 
Bank  of  England 

Div.  %,  5th  April      . 
Div.  o/o,  5th  Oct. 
Bank  of  Ireland 

Div.  %,  1st  Feb. 

Div.  %,  1st  Aug. 
^%     India,     1931 

Money.      (Int.    Jan., 

April,  July,  Oct.) 
3%  India,  1948  Money 

(Int.  Jan.,  Apr.,  Jxine, 

Oct.) 
2i%    India,  1926 

Money.      (Int.    Jan., 

April,  Julv,  Oct.) 
3i%  India  Bonds, 

1916-18.  (Int.  April, 

Oct.) 


84} 

79;? 

84 
79i 


84J  I  791 
76i  1  73 

83, \,   79f 
76J  I  74J 


92   92i  I  86i 
83}  i  79i 

96J  I  94i  :  90i  87i 

92J   --    - 

93 

91i 


76y\  79J  67 J 
691  69   65i 


65t 
50i 


76} 

70i''c 

82J 
75} 


94  J 

85J 

82i 

94 

91} 


95} 
91} 

94i 

91} 
106} 
102} 
272 
250 
9 
9 
314} 
293 

11} 

12 

94} 
92} 

84} 
79} 

70} 
66 


94}  94} 

93  U  92| 

97}  95} 

92}  88 

84}  84 

82  79} 


82   81  t', 


91} 
89} 


96} 
90} 

95;^ 
91} 
106} 
1102} 
263 
242} 

9 
303 
269 

12 

12 

97| 
91 


78 

71 
65} 

101} 
99ri 


87} 
87} 


96 

92} 

90} 

88 

79} 

73} 

87* 

87} 


79}  68} 
72}   66} 

i 
86}  :  74} 
74  j  71} 

89}  !  81} 
81f   78} 
97  i  94} 
95  1  89 
95}  1  90 
89}  \   87} 
80}  75} 
78   75 
92} 
92} 


83   83} 

79  rJ  79} 
83   83 
81,il  78 
100}  101} 
99  !  98 

100  J  lOOJ 
99}  97  J, 

101  100} 
99}  1  96 

102}  101} 
100}  99} 


93}  91}   95 
87}  86}  88} 


92}  91 

88}  :  86} 

104}  102} 

101}  99} 

251   251 

234   224} 

9    9 

9  1  9 

280}  243 

240   215 

11    10 

10   10 

94}  91} 

89}  {  84,'s 

80}  78} 
76}   71 

67}  65 
63}  ;  60} 

100}f,  100} 
99}  98} 


60^  71 
53}   55 


71} 

54  *„ 


61} 
55 


78}  61} 

57}  56i 

91}  I  93} 

91}  I  90} 

72}  j  69} 

68  66} 

75,>„  75} 


63 
53} 

63} 
56} 

67 
57} 


58} 
51} 

63 
53} 

64 
54} 


90} 
86 


94} 
87} 
103} 

101}  ! 

256  249} 

234  230 

10  I  10 

10  ,10 

'240}  230} 

222}  182} 

10   10 

10   10 


93} 
84 

80} 
71} 


66} 


66}  64} 

58}  !  55} 

97}  99} 

94 

72} 

66} 

80 

74 

71 

69} 


88}  68 
62}  63} 


86 

63 

97 

75 
230} 
194} 

10 

10 


66 

63 

79} 

72 
205 
190 

10 

10 


200}  195 

172  170 

10  10 

10  10 


83}  80}  69} 
80}  63}  1  62} 


98} 

73} 

61 

84} 

79 

69} 

64} 

74} 

70} 

73} 
62 

70 
62 

87} 
74 
224} 
186} 
10 
10 

223  226 

190  204 

10   12 

10   12 


70} 
67} 

70 
63} 
83} 
71 

226 

191} 
10 
10 


711 
69} 


66}   60} 
59  ;  57 


100, 
96  ■ 


69} 
54} 


60}  64 
53}  53 


74 
61} 


57}  SO 
46}  1  45} 


97f?  98}  I  99} 
97}  j  96}  I  99} 


53} 
44} 


71} 
60 

61} 
50} 

51 J 
43} 


192 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC    FINANCE 


QUOTATIONS  LONDON  STOCK  EXCHANGE  [Continued). 
British  Funds. 


Calendar  Years. 

1910    1911 

1912 

1913 

1914    1915 

1916 

1917 

1918  [  1919 

Name. 

t 

3J%       Indian      Rupee 

Paper.    (Int.  various 

H 

6!H 

64» 

64J 

64 

64* 

tii;}, 

M4 

53 

534 

68 

Dates)      . 

L 

6'2i 

62i 

63i 

62i 

63i 

54 

48* 

424 

43 

484 

3i%       Indian       Rupee 

Paper,  1854-5.     :(Int. 

H 

64 

64» 

64» 

64i 

Mkh 

624 

55 

524 

54 

68r 

June,  Dec.) 

L 

62J 

63i 

63i 

63 

63i 

52 

48J 

4:^4 

43 

48: 

3%  Indian  Rupee  Paper 

1896-7.       (Int.   June, 

H 

53 

52i 

541 

54 

53i 

494 

454 

384 

414      58 

Dec.) 

L 

52 

52 

53» 

53} 

534 

484 

434 

3V4 

414      43 

3i%  Isle  of  Man.    (Int. 

H 

96J 

97,1, 

96+ 

94 

99 

99i 

96  r!, 

89i 

99,',!  994 

Feb.,  Aug.)        . 

L 

96i 

974 

964 

94 

964 

96 

89 

97}  !  97 

3%   Isle  of  Man  Deb., 

1919-29.      (Int.  Feb., 
Aug.)        . 

H 

881 
88i 

87J 
85J 

804 

794 

L 

80 

77J 

Authorities  for  Quotat'Ons  1910-1919,  Investors'  Monthly  Manual — London.  Stock 
Exchanges  London  and  Provincial  Ten-Year  Record  of  Prices  and  Dividends — 1909-1918, 
Mathieson,  Fred  C.  C.  &  Sons,  London,  1919.     Mathieson's  Handbook  for  Investors  for  1920. 


QUOTATIONS. 

NEW  YORK   STOCK  EXCHANGE. 

British  Funds. 


Calendar  Years. 

1914 

1915 

1 
916 

1917 

1918 

1919 

Name. 

5%    Anglo-French 

5yr.     . 

H 

984 

964 

934 

974 

97J 

(Int.  Apr.  and  Oct.) 

L 

93J 

924 

814 

884 

954 

United  Kingdom  of 

Great  Britain  and 

Ireland 

2  yr.  5%  Notes  1918. 

H 

99}J 

98 

(Int.  Mch.  &  Sept.) 

L 

98 

95 

3  yr.   54%   Notes 

1919     . 

H 

98} 

98J 

100 

(Int.  May  &  Nov.) 

L 

974 

934 

954 

5  yr.   54%   Notes 

1921      . 

U 

984 

984 

99 

91  i 

994 

(Int.  May  &  Nov.) 

L 

97 

844 

94} 

54%  Convertible 

Notes  . 

H 

lOOi 

1918     . 

L 

98 

54%  Convertible 

Notes  1919    . 

H 

1014 

105 

(Int.  Feb.  &  Aug.) 

L 

954 

974 

54%  20  yr.  Gold  Bond 

1937     . 

H 

101 

1014 

(Int.  Feb.   &  Aug.) 

L 

100 

96$ 

10  yr.  Conv.  54s  19-9 

H 

(Int.  Feb.   &  Aug.) 

L 

944 

3  yr.  Conv.  54s  1922 

H 

984 

(Int.  Feb.  &  Aug.) 

L 

954 

NATIONAL    DEBT 


193 


MONEY   RATES. 
London  Daily  Average. 

Bank  Rate. 


1914 

1915 

1916 

1917 

1918 

1919 

First  half 
Second  half  . 

3  4     7 

4  16   10 

i    s.   d. 
5     0     0 
5     0     0 

i    s.    d. 
5     0     0 
5   18     6 

i     S.     d.£     5.     d. 

5     6     05     0     0 
5     0     05     0     0 

£  s.  d. 

5     0     0 
5     6     0 

Whole  year  . 

4     0     9 

5     0     0 

5     9     3 

5     3     05     0     0 

5     3     0 

Market  Rate — Three  Months  Bills. 

First  half 
Second  half  . 

1  s.    d. 

2  10     2 

3  5     3 

1  s.    d. 

2  9     0 
4   19     3 

i    s.    d.l    s.    d.\£    s.    d.£    s.    d. 

4  17     64   16     73  13     03  10     0 

5  11     04  15     93  10     54     7     9 

Whole  year  . 

2   17     8 

3  14     1 

5     4     34   16     23  11     93  18  10 

Deposit  Rate — Banks. 

First  half 
Second  half  . 

£  s.  d. 

1  14     7 

2  10     0 

£    s.    d.\£    s.    d}£    s.    d. 

2  0     03  10     0,4     0     0 

3  4     13  18     94     0     0 

£  s.  d. 

3     2     0 
3     0     0 

£  s.  d. 
3   0   a 
379 

Whole  year  . 

2     2     42  12     o's  14     4I4     0     0 

3     1     0 

3   3  10. 

Short  Loans. 

First  half      . 
Second  half   . 

£    s.    d.t;^    s.    d. 

1  1     1\\1  11 

2  5  114     3     9 

£    s.    d.\£    s.    d. 
4     5  114  11     0 
4  19     64     5     6 

£  s.  d. 

3     6     2 
3     4  11 

£  s.  d. 

3     4     7 
3  14     7 

Whole  year   . 

2     4     32  18     4 

4   12     84     8     3 

3     5     6397 

TREASURY  BILLS. 

Discount  Rate. 


Rate 

Date. 

% 

Maturity. 

1917. 

19th  June 

4f 

3  and  6  months  bills. 

27th  Dec. 

4 

1918. 

14th  Feb. 

3^ 

i>              i>           >> 

1919. 

31st   May 

— 

Sales  discontinued. 

14th  July 

H 

2  months  bills — (Sales  discontinued  15th  August), 

H 

3 

4 

6 

6th     Oct. 

4i 

3 

5 

6 

7th    Nov. 

5i 

3  and  6  months  bills. 

For  further  data  about  Treasury  Bills,  see  Item  21,  page  185,  also  Index. 
13— (1823) 


194 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


SOVEREIGNS  OF  ENGLAND. 
From  the  Conquest. 


Reign    Reigned, 
Sovereign.  began,   years. 

Norman  Line. 

William  the  Conqueror      .     1066  21 

WiUiam  Rufus            .          .      1087  13 

Henry  I  .                   .          .     1 100  35 

Stephen  .          .          .          .1135  19 


House  of  Plantagenet. 


Henry  II 
Richard  I 
John 

Henry  III 
Edward  I 
Edward  II 
Edward  III 
Richard  IF 


1154 
1189 
119L) 
1216 
1272 
1307 
1327 
1377 


House  of  Lancaster. 


Henry  IV 
Henry  V 
Henry  VI» 


1399 
1413 
1422 


House  of  York. 


Edward  IV 
Edward  V 
Richard  III 


1461 
1483 
1483 


House  of  Tudor. 


Henry  VII 
Henry  VIII 
Edward  VI 


1485 
1509 
1547 


Deposed  1399. 
Deposed  1461. 


35 
10 
17 
56 
35 
20 
50 
22 


Sovereign. 


Reign   Reigned, 
began,     years. 


Mary  I 
Elizabeth 


1553 
1558 


House  of  Stuart. 


James  I   .         .         .         .     1603 
Charles  I »         .  .  .     1625 

Commonwealth  declared 

May  19th,     1649 
Oliver  Cromwell 

Lord  Protector  1653-1658 
Richard  Cromwell 

Lord  Protector  1658-1659 
Charles  II         .  .  .     1660 

James  II*  .         .  .     1685 

WUUam  III   J 

and  V  .  .     1689 

Mary  IP        ) 
Anne       ....     1702 


House  of  Hanover. 


George  I 
George  II 
George  III 
George  IV 
WiUiam  IV 
Victoria  . 


House  op  Kent. 
Edward  VII     .  .         .     1901 

House  of  Windsor. 
George  V  .         .         .     1910 

'  Beheaded  1649. 
'  Deposed  1688. 
■*  Died  1694. 


5 
45 


22 
24 


13 


1714 

13 

1727 

33 

1760 

60 

1820 

10 

1830 

7 

1837 

64 

national  debt  195 

Authorities. 

The  statements  contained  in  this  book  are  for  the  most 
part  based  upon  official  data,  chiefly  derived  from  the 
following  publications — 

Period.  Revenue,  Expenditure,  Currency  and  Debt. 

1688-1869  House  of  Commons  Sessional  Papers,  Vol.  XXXV,  1868-69, 
No.  366.  This  monumental  work  of  H.  W.  Chisholm  gives 
complete  data  in  regard  to  revenue  and  expenditure  and 
the  debt. 

1870-1919      Finance  Accounts.     See  page  140. 

1919  and       Budget  Speeches  as  printed  in  various  publications  ;    also 

1920  semi-official  data  tabulated  in  The  Economist  and  The 
Statist. 

1914-1919  Committee  on  Currency  and  Foreign  Exchanges  After  the  War 
— Lord  Cunlifie,  Chairman.  First  Interim  Report — C. 
9182,  1918.     Final  Report— C.  464,  1919. 

The  Debt. 
1694-1786      History  of  the  Earlier  Years  of  the  Funded  Debt.     A.  T.  King. 

House  of  Commons  Sessional  Papers,   1898.     Vol.  LII — 

C.  9010. 
1786-1890      Proceedings  of  the  Commissioners  for  the  Reduction  of  the 

National    Debt.     House    of    Commons    Sessional    Papers, 

1891.     Vol.  XLVIII— C.  6539. 
1836-1914      National    Debt.     House    of    Commons    Sessional    Papers, 

1914.     Vol.  L — C.  7426.     Similar  statements  are  published 

annually. 

Rev'enue,  Expenditure  and  Debt. 
Of  secondary  sources  the  most  valuable  have  been — 

AsHTON,     John. — A     History     of  from    the    earliest    times    to    the 

English    Lotteries.          London,  present  day.     London,  1884. 

1893.  The  authoritative  work  on  the  subject. 

The  best  authority.  Freeman,       Edward       A. — The 

Atton,      Henry,      and     Henry  Growth  of  the  English  Constitu- 

HuRST  Holland. — The  King's  Hon    from    the    Earliest    Times. 

Customs.     New  York,   1908.  London,  1906. 

Covers  from  earliest  times  to  1800.  GiFFEN,  Robert. — The  Growth  of 

BoGART,   Ernest  L. — Direct  and  Capital.     London,  1889. 

Indirect  Costs  of  the  Great  World  ^  exceUent  study  of  national  wealth. 

War.  Hall,  Hubert. — The  Antiquities 

Carnegie  Endowment  for  International  «"^  Curiosities  of  the  Exchequer. 

Peace.     New  York,  1919.  London,    1891. 

Brisco,     Norris     a.— The     Eco-  Supplements  Madox.    See  below. 

nomic  Policy  of  Robert  Walpole.  ^  History  of  the  Custom  Revenue 

New  York,  1907.  "^   England  to    1827.      2   Vols. 

A   finished   study;     the   best   for   the  London,  1885. 

period.  Mr.  Hall  is  one  of  the  most  thorough 

DowELL,  Stephen.— /i  History  of  students  of  early  fiscal  methods.    His 

™        ,.             J  _           ._,-','  historv    of    the    Customs    is    the    best 

1  axation  and  Faxes  m  England,  authority. 


196 


ENGLISH   PUBLIC   FINANCE 


/. 


4 


Hamilton,  Robert. — An  Inquiry 
Concerning  ....  the  National 
Debt.     Edinburgh,  1818. 

A  scientific  study.  Hamilton  deserves 
the  credit  for  convincingly  demon- 
strating the  fallacy  of  Pitt's  sinking  fund. 
A  concise,  authoritative  exposition  of 
the  subject. 

HiGGS,  Henry.  The  Financial 
System  of  the  United  Kingdom. 
London,  1914. 

A  summary  exposition  of  our  financial 
sj'stem,  its  organization,  methods  and 
forms  of  procedure. 

Hughes,  A.,  Crump,  C.  G.,  and 
Johnson,  C. — "  De  Necessaries 
Observantiis  Scaccarii  Dialogus," 
commonly  called  Dialogus  de 
Scaccario,  by  Richard,  Son  of 
Nigel,  Treasurer  of  England  and 
Bishop  of  London.  Oxford, 
1902. 

Supplements  Madox.  A  recent  and  very 
thorough  study. 

Lowell,     A.     Lawrence. — The 
Government  of  England.    2  Vols. 
New  York,  1912. 
The  best  authority  on  English  govern- 
mental methods. 

Madox,    Thomas. — The    Ancient 
Dialogue    Concerning    the    Ex- 
chequer.    London,  1758. 
The  best  authority  on  the  earliest  history 
of  EngUsh  public  finance. 

Poole,    Reginald    L. — The    Ex- 
chequer   in    the    \2th    Century. 
Oxford,  1912. 
Supplements  Madox. 

Ramsay,  Sir  James  H.  of  Bampf. 

The  historical  works  of  this  author 
cover  the  period  of  English  history 
from  B.C.  55  to  A.D.  1485.  He  gives 
particular  attention  to  matters  of  finance, 
and  is  perhaps  the  best  authority  on 
public  finance  from  1154,  when  the  first 
records  become  available,  to  1485.  He 
is  reputed  to  be  very  accurate. 

ScoTT,  W.  R. — The  Constitution 
and  Finance  of  English,  Scottish 
and  Irish  Joint  Stock  Companies 
to  1720.  3  Vols.  Cambridge, 
1910-1912. 

An  extremely  valuable  study.  Vol.  HI 
contains  data  in  re  Crown  finance  in  the 
time  of  Queen  Elizabeth  not  to  be 
found  elsewhere. 
Scroggs,  W.  O. — English  Finances 
under     the     Long     Parliament. 


Quarterly'  Journal  of  Economics. 

May,  1907. 

An  important  study. 

SiLBERLiNG,  NoRMAN  J. — British 
Financial  Experience,  1 790- 1 830. 
In  The  (Harvard)  Review  of 
Economic  Statistics,  October, 
1919. 

An  excellent  study  of  commodity  prices, 
/   wages,  prices  of  gold  and  silver,  exchange, 
and  interest  rates. 

Sinclair,  Sir  John. — The  History 
of  the  Public  Revenue  of  the  Brit- 
ish Empire.  3  Vols.  London, 
1803-04. 

The  authority  on  the  history  of  Crown 
and  national  finance  to  about  1801. 
Treats  also  of  early  borrowing  methods. 

Stamp,  J.  C. — British  Incomes 
and    Property.     London,    1916. 

The  Wealth  and  Income  of  the 
Chief  Powers.  Journal  Royal 
Stat.  Soc.     July,  1919. 

Probably  the  most  scientific  and  authori- 
tative studies  which  have  been  made  on 
these  subjects. 

Stubbs,  William. — The  Constitu- 
tional History  of  England  in  its 
Origin  and  Developynent  (1066- 
1485).  3  Vols.  Oxford,  1880. 
The  standard  work  on  the  English 
Constitution.     Invaluable. 

Williams,  W.  M.  J. — The  King's 
Revenue.     London,  1908. 
An  excellent  guide  to  a  correct  imder- 
standing  of  Treasury  and  budget  state- 
ments. 

WlLLOUGHBY,WM.F.,andWESTEL, 

W.  ;  McCuNE,  Samuel  Lind- 
say.— The  System  of  Financial 
Administration  of  Great  Britain. 
New  York,  1917. 

Describes  particularly  the  English  budget 
system. 

Banking. 

ANDR^ADis,    A. — History    of   the 
Bank    of    England.        London, 
1909. 
The  acknowledged  best  authority. 

Bagehot,        Walter. — Lombard 
Street.     New  York,  1912. 
For  administrative  methods. 


NATIONAL    DEBT 


197 


BisscHOP,  W.  R. — The  Rise  of  the 
London  Money  Market.  Lon- 
don, 1910. 

Of  especial  value  in  connection  with  the 
genesis  and  history  of  the  private  and 
joint  stock  banks. 

Francis,  Joseph  Hume. — History 
of  the  Bank  of  England.  Chicago, 
1888. 
For  human  interest  notes. 

HoLDEN,  Sir  Edward  H. — 
Annual  addresses  to  Share- 
holders of  the  London  Joint 
City  &  Midland  Bank. 

These  very  able  addresses  were  delivered 
at  the  annual  meetings,  1915  to  1919 
inclusive. 

Palgrave,  R.  H.  Inglis. — Bank 
Rate  and  the  Money  Market. 
New  York,  1903. 

An  invaluable  study  of  the  banking 
reserves  and  discount  rates  from   1845. 


Philippovich,  Eugen  von. — His- 
tory of  the  Bank  of  England. 
Washington,  1911. 

For     relations      to      the      Exchequer. 
Authoritative. 

Powell,  Ellis  T. — The  Evolution 
of  the  Money  Market.  London, 
1916. 

a    study   of   finance    as    a    central    co- 
ordinated force. 

Rogers,  James  E. — The  First 
Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of 
England.     London. 

The  standard  authority  for  the  period 
covered. 

Withers,  Hartley. — The  English 
Banking  System.  Washington, 
1911. 

a     concise    review     prepared     for    the 
National  Monetary  Commission. 

War  and  Lombard  Street.    Lon- 
don, 1917. 

For    emergency    measures    adopted    at 
outbreak  of  war. 


The   Economist,   The  Statist,  and   The  Bankers'  Magazine,  London, 
have  been  of  the  greatest  value,  particularly  for  the  war  period. 


Index  and  Glossary 

Where  no  page  number  is  given  the  subject  is  not  treated  in  the  text. 


Acceptances,    Use    of,    7,    How 

market  was  protected  in  1914,  7 
Accounting  Officers  of  Exchequer, 

140 
Aid,  57 — See  Scutage,  taxation 
Aids,  Feudal,  53 
Alfred,  Kang,  49 
Allies  and   Dominions,   Loans  to 

31st  March,  1920,  Table,  29 
American  Securities,  Mobilization 

of,  1914-1919,  20 

War — See  War 

Amsterdam,  Bank  ot,  established 

1609,  80,  154 

Anglo-French  Loan,  20 — See  also 
Debt  Table,  182 

Anglo-Saxon  Kings,  Finances,  49- 
52 

Anne,  Queen,  89 

Annuities,  87 

Antiqua  Custuma,  i.e.,  The 
ancient  and  equitable  duties,  56 

Assessments,  Monthly,  58 

Assets,  National,  17 

Assize  of  Arms.  A  medieval 
term.  Under  the  assize  every 
freeman  was  required  to  pro- 
vide himself  with  arms  and 
armour  according  to  his  means 
and  rank  and  to  stand  ready 
for  military  service. 

Australia,  Cost  of  War,  1914- 
1919,  1 

Auxilia.  A  medieval  tax  on 
tenants. 

Banco  del  Giro,  153 

' della  Piazza  del  Rialto,  153 

Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844 — See 
Bank  of  England,  170 

of  Amsterdam,  154 

of  England  :      Advances    to 

Government  on  Credit  of  Ways 
and  Means,  36  ;  Bank  Act  of 
1844,  terms  of,  170,  171  ;  sus- 
pension of  in  1847,  1857,  1866 
and  1914,  172  ;  Bank  Rate- 
Effect  of  in  regulating  money 


rates  and  the  exchanges,  148, 
normally  controls  money  mar- 
ket, 148  ;  Branches,  169  ;  Build- 
ing, 177  ;  BuUion  Report  1810, 
164  ;  Capital  —  original,  158  ; 
Charter  granted,  24th  July, 
1694,  75  ;  Charter  Act  of  1844, 
169  ;  Clerical  machinery,  177  ; 
"  The  Court,"  176  ;  Commit- 
tees, 176  ;  Crises,  18th  Century, 
and  the  Bank,  1 60  ;  Directors — 
How  elected,  174  ;  personnel, 
174,  committees  of,  176, 
court  of,  176  ;  Early  His- 
tory, 157  ;  Exchequer — rela- 
tion to,  137  ;  First  bank  in 
modem  sense,  147  ;  Fund  of 
Credit  idea,  88,  158  ;  French 
War,  Great,  and  the  bank,  161  ; 
Functions — acts  as  banker  to 
nation,  138,  148,  159,  carries 
reserves  of  other  banks,  148, 
conducts  general  banking  busi- 
ness, 147,  issues  bank  notes, 
147,  mobilizes  national  credit 
resources,  149  ;  Fund  of  Credit, 
88,  158  ;  Government  of,  174, 
committees,  176,  clerical  ma- 
chinery, 177,  directorate,  174  ; 
Governor  and  Deputy  Gover- 
nor— How  selected,  174,  change 
every  two  years,  176,  duties, 
176  ;  Loan  from  Bank  of 
France  in  1839,  170  ;  Note  issue 
— rights  in  England  practically 
exclusive,  147  ;  Notes  made 
legal  tender  in  1833,  169  ; 
Officers,  175  ;  Origin,  157  ; 
Privately  owned,  158 ;  Privi- 
leges and  obligations  under 
Act  of  1844,  171  ;  Quotations 
for  stock,  188 ;  Reserves — 
ultimate  banking  r.  of  nation 
held,  148  ;  Reserves — rule  in  re 
prior  to  1844,  170  ;  Reserves  in 
1839,  170  ;  Rest  (reserve)  estab- 
lished 1722,  169,  Restriction  Act, 
163  ;   Resumes  specie  payments 


199 


200 


INDEX   AND    GLOSSARY 


in  1821,  165  ;  Rule  for  Conduct 
of  business  prior  to  1844,  170; 
Statements  required,  169,  com- 
ment of  the  Economist  thereon, 
170 ;  Stockholders'  liabihty, 
169  ;  Specie  payments  sus- 
pended 1797-1821,  162  ;  effect 
on  exchanges  and  prices, 
163 
Bank  of  France  :  Founded  in  1800, 
171  ;  Loan  to  Bank  of  England 
in  1839,  170 

of  Genoa  or  Compania  (Casa) 

di  San  Giorgio,  Origin  dates 
from  1148,   154 

of  Ireland,  138 

of  Venice  or  Banco  del  Giro, 

Founded  1619,  153 

Bankers — Itahan  and  Plantagenet 
Kings,  151 

Banking — Italian  corporate  banks 
— eariy,   153 

,  Joint-stock — Introduced    in 

1826,76,166;  Privilege  extend- 
ed to  London  1833,  76.  English 
forbidden  to  issue  notes,  166, 
167,  171  ;  Number  of  banks 
still  having  privileges  in  1920, 
167  ;  Number  and  resources  in 
Dec,   1919,   168 

credits — How   created,    37  ; 

How  they  helped  to  finance  war 
1914-1920,  33;  Reserves  v. 
Credits,  34 

Reserves — v.  Credits,   1914- 

1920,  34  ;  ntimate  carried  in 
Bank  of  England,  148  ;  Scotch, 
148,  179 

Statements — not  required  in 

England  except  by  Bank  of 
England,  169 

Banks,  Country — failures  in  1793, 
108,  160 

,  Irish,  148,  179 

Banks  or  Partnerships  of  more 
than  six  persons  forbidden  in 
1708  to  issue  notes  in  England, 
166;  In  1826  restrictions  re- 
moved (until  1844)  on  banks 
located  65  miles  from  London, 
167 

Benevolences,  60 

Bona  Vacantia,  54 

Boer  War,  30 

Borrowing — See  Debt 

Brig-bote,  49 


British  Empire,  Cost  of  War  to 
1914-1919.  1 

Budget,  134 

From  the  French  bougette,  a 
little  bag  in  which  the  Chan- 
cellor of  the  Exchequer  kept  his 
papers.  Adopted  in  England 
in  1763  when  the  annual 
statement  of  the  plan  of  supplies 
and  means  was  first  called 
"  opening  the  Budget." 

(1920-1921).  15 

Bullion  Report,  164 
Burg-bote,  49 

Canada— Cost  of  War  to  (1914- 
1919),  1 

Capital  Levy  urged  in  1715.  101 

Chamberlain,  Austen,  15,  16,  17, 
18,  22,  29 

Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer — 
Ancient  times,  130  ;  Modem 
times,  134,  136 — See  Chamber- 
lain. Austen  ;  Gladstone,  Wil- 
liam ;  North,  Lord  ;  Pitt, 
William  ;    Walpole,  Robert 

Charles  I — Government  without 
Parliament,  69 

II,  65,  70 ;  Army  dis- 
banded, 71  ;  Clergy  consent  to 
be  taxed  by  Parliament  and 
obtain  right  to  vote  at  elections, 
72  ;  Dutch  wars,  72  ;  Excise 
Taxes,  72  ;  Fire  of  London.  72  ; 
French  loan  makes  him  inde- 
pendent of  Parliament,  73  ; 
Seizes  deposits  of  Goldsmiths, 
65  ;  Parliament  ends  Dutch  war 
by  withholding  supplies,  72  ; 
Plague,  72  ;  Poll  tax — greatest 
known — cla.sses  affected,  71  ; 
Stop  of  Exchequer,  65,  72,  156  ; 
Revenue  —  lOths  and  15ths 
abandoned  for  monthly  assess- 
ments, 72  ;  Permanent  revenue 
given  in  lieu  of  prerogative 
rights,  72 

Charters  :  Magna — extorted  from 
King  John  in  1215.  The  great 
charter  of  the  liberties  of  Eng- 
land, 47.  57,  66 — See  Taxation  : 
Aids,  Customs,  Escheats,  Scut- 
age,  Purveyance.  Mercatoria — 
published  in  1303.  The  Magna 
Charta  of  Commerce.  The  basis 
of  the  free  trade  system,  66 


INDEX   AND    GLOSSARY 


201 


Chisholm,  H.  W.,  Monumental 
reports  on  debt  and  revenue, 
114,  195 

Church,  The,  Revenues  derived 
from,  68  ;  Spoliation  of  by 
Henry  VIII,  68 

Circulation,  Bank  Note  :  English, 
166,  167  ;  Bank  of  England, 
169-173  ;  Joint-stock  banks, 
166  ;  Private  banks,  167  ;  Irish 
banks,  179  ;  Scotch  banks, 
179 

Civil  Government,  Cost  of,  1833- 
1920,  124-126 

Rights,   Revenues  and  civil 

rights,  histories  bound  together, 
47 

War  Period.   1649-1660,  69 

Clergy  :    Supplies  voted  from  own 

estate  until  time  Charles  II,  72  ; 
Obtain  right  to  vote  at  elections, 
72 

Coinage  :  Debasement  as  source 
of  revenue,  54,  60  ;  Debased  by 
Edw^ard  I,  Edward  IV,  Henry 
VIII,  60;  Irish— debased  by 
Elizabeth,  61  ;  Restored  by 
EUzabeth,  61  ;  Restored  by 
V^^iUiam  III,  61 

Commerce,  Foreign,  Anglo-Saxon, 
50 

Commons  :  First  admitted  to 
share  in  taxing  power  (1295), 
66 ;  Certain  revenues  voted 
yearly  to  insure  control  of 
government,  118  ;  Right  to  ini- 
tiate money  legislation  becomes 
a  precedent  in  reign  of  Henry 
IV,  67;  WilHam  III  and, 
118 

Commonwealth  and  Protectorate 
(1649-1659):  A  period  of  active 
training  for  self-rule,  69  ;  Cost 
of  government  high,  70 

Compania  di  San  Giorgio,  154 

Compera  del  Capitalo,  154 

"  Consols,"  105,  183 

Constitutional  Government 
veloped  by  control  of 
under  Plantagenets,  66  ; 
caster  and  York,  67  ;  Tudors, 
67  ;  Stuarts  (earlier),  68  ;  Com- 
monwealth and  Protectorate, 
69  ;  Stuarts  (later),  70  ;  Wilham 
III,  48 

Continental    Policy,    Napoleon's, 


De- 
purse 
Lan- 


Stimulated  home  trade  of  Eng- 
land, 163 

Contributions — See  Revenue 

Corn  Laws  repealed,  77 

Cotton  Trade,  How  financed,  1914, 
10 

Credit,  Letter  of,  reign  of  John, 
152 

■,  National,     High     sense     of 

national  honour  at  base  of 
national  credit,  117 

Structure  :     In   war,    1914- 

1920,  39 

Credits,  Loans  to  Dominions  and 
Allies,  31st  March,  1920— Table, 
29 

Cromwell,  70 

Crown  Colonies,  Cost  of  war  to, 
1914-1919,  1 

Finance,  1066-1688,  47 

Lands,  59 

Jewels  Pawned  for  Debt,  62 

Crusades  and  Italian  bankers,  151 
Cunliffe,     Lord,     Committee     on 

Currency  and  Foreign  Ex- 
changes, 36 

Currency  and  Foreign  Exchanges 
after  War,  Committee  on,  36 

— — ,  Joint-stock  Banks  deprived 
of  right  to  issue  notes  in  1844, 
171;  Note  and  Deposit — actual 
and  per  capita,  1913-1919, 
Table  II,  42  ;  Note  and  deposit 
V.  Gold  Reserves,  Table  III,  44 

notes — See   Treasury   Notes 

Customs,   55  ;    Anglo-Saxon,   50  ; 

Antiqua-Custuma,  56  ;  Farm- 
ing, 150  ;  Free  Trade — absolute 
since  1866,  77  ;  Charta  Merca- 
toria,  66  ;  Informal,  56  ;  Magna 
Charta,  defined,  56  ;  New  Cus- 
toms (Nova  Custuma)  56  ;  Old 
(Antiqua-Custuma),  56  ;  Oldest 
branch  of  revenue,  55  ;  Origin, 
50,  55  ;  Prisage — two  casks  of 
wine  from  each  cargo,  56 ; 
Protective  Tariffs,  56  ;  Sub- 
sidies, 56  ;  Tariffs  to  promote 
and  regulate  commerce,  56  ; 
Tariff  reform,  122  ;  Tunnage 
and  Poundage,  56 

Dane-geld,  49 

Debt,  Crown  :  Compulsive  loans, 
64  ;  Crown  jewels  pawmed  for 
debt,  62  ;    First  recorded,  62  ; 


202 


INDEX   AND   GLOSSARY 


Foreign  borrowing,  64  ;  Interest 
payments  (usury)  interdict  in 
medieval  times,  62  ;  Henry 
VIII  repudiates,  63  ;  Security 
given — form  of,  63  ;  Stop  of 
Exchequer,  65 
Debt  National  :  Ability  to  carry 
due  to  progress  of  the  arts  and 
sciences,  etc.,  during  18th  and 
19th  Centuries,  32,  115,  128; 
American  War  (1775-1783),  94  ; 
Amount  at  close  of  historical 
periods,  1688-1817,  81  ;  1817- 
1919,  31  ;  Annuities,  87  ;  ton- 
tine, 87  ;  V.  Bank  Assets,  39  ; 
Began  in  1688,  74,  79,  82  ; 
Burden,  Comparative,  1688— 
1817,  114,  116;  1688-1920,  15, 
142-5;    1817-1914,128;    1817- 

1919,  30,  31  ;  Cause,  chieflv 
war,  76,  79.  112,  119,  143,  145"; 
Charge  v.  National  Income,  30, 
115,  128;  Competitive  bidding 
for  loans,  inaugurated  by  Pitt, 
107  ;    "  Consols,"  origin,   1749, 

105,  183  ;  Consols,  quotations, 
1697-1920,  188,  190;  Credits 
to  31st  March,  1920,  29  ; 
Debenture — copy  of  one  in 
reign  of  John,  151  ;  East  India 
Co.,  89  ;  Exchequer  Bills,  75, 
85,  86  ;  Exchequer  bonds,  184  ; 
Exchequer  order  and  tallies,  83  ; 
Floating      debt— 1784,      106; 

1920,  25,  27  ;  Foreign  securi- 
ties mobilization,  1915,  20  ; 
French  War  Debt,  108-117; 
"  Funded  "  and  "  unfunded  " 
debt  defined,  82  ;  Funded,  early 
forms,  87  ;  Fund  of  Credit, 
88  ;  Loans  to  Dominions  and 
AlUes,  31st  March,  1920— 
Table,  29  ;  Lottery  Loans,  93, 
Lotteries,  State,  97  ;  Loyalty 
Loan  of  1796,  110;  Maturities 
of  debt  on  31st  Dec,  1919,  25  ; 
Navy  supply  bills — manner  of 
issue  time  Charles  II  to   1784, 

106,  discount  in  market,  1687, 
85,  method  of  issue  reformed 
by  Pitt,  106,  funded  by  Pitt  in 
1785  and  1786,  106  ;  Origin. 
74  ;  Paying  for  the  War  bonds, 
35  ;   Reduction,  Proposed  1920- 

1921,  26,  27;  Refunding  and 
reduction  of  interest.  1749,  105, 


1784,  106,  1817-1914,  127, 
1920-1921,  26,  27  ;  Sinking 
Fund  :  Walpole's,  1717,  101, 
after  1727  inoperative  for  debt 
reduction,  102  ;  Sinking  Fund, 
Pitt's,  1786-1829.  102,  fallacy 
of.  103,  Sinking  Pounds,  Modern. 
104.  186.  old,  186,- new,  186. 
war  debt,  1914-1920  (known 
as  depreciation  fund  for  4% 
and  5%  War  Loans  ;  Sinking 
Fund  for  Victory  and  Funding 
Loans),  14,  26,  187;  31st  March, 
1920,  complete  descriptive 
tables,  181-187  ;  Spanish  and 
Austrian  Wars  debt  (1739- 
1748),  81,  82  ;  Terms  on  which 
loans  were  placed,  American 
War,  95-99,  Great  French 
War,  108.  109,  114,  Great 
World  War,  1914-1920.  19-25  ; 
Transfer  regulations,  186  ; 
Treasury  Bills,  8,  11,  27,  75. 
185  ;  Treasurv  Bonds,  27  ; 
Unfunded  debt  defined,  82, 
early  forms  of,  83 — army  and 
navy  supply  bills,  85,  exchequer 
bills,  85,  86,  exchequer  bonds, 
184,  exchequer  order,  84,  tallies, 
83,  treasury  bills,  8,  11.  185, 
ways  and  means  advances,  36  ; 
War  Debt.  1914-1920,  19; 
War  Savings  Associations, 
1914-1920,  21  ;  v.  Wealth, 
1688-1817,  81  ;    1817-1914,  128 

"  Demesne  " — Domain,  49,  53 — 
See  Prerogative 

Discount  Rates — Money,  1898- 
1914,  4;    1914-1919.  193 

Dominions  and  Allies— Loans  to. 
31st  March.  1920,  2,  17  ;  Table, 
29 

Dominions  :  Expenditures  for 
War,  1914-1919,  1,  2  ;  Per 
cent,  met  by  taxation,  3 

East  India  Company,  89 
Edward  the  Confessor,  49 

I  :      Coinage    Debased,    60, 

Commons  admitted  to  share  in 
taxing  powers  in  1295,  66 ; 
Laws  codified  by,  66  ;  Tannage 
and  Poundage  originate  in 
reign  of,  56 

Ill  :  Default  on  obliga- 
tions  to  Italian  bankers,   153  ; 


INDEX    AND    GLOSSARY 


203 


Necessity  for  revenue  gives 
Parliament  opportunity  to  ob- 
tain concessions  in  exchange  for 
grants,  67  ;  Poll  tax  first  laid  in 
1337  ;  Tenths  and  Fifteenths 
originated  in  his  reign,  57 
Edward  IV,  Coinage  debased,  60 

VI,    Foreign   loans,    64,   68, 

152 

Elizabeth,  Queen,  Foreign  loans, 
64,  152  ;  Lottery,  93  ;  Coinage 
restored,  60  ;  Sanctions  base 
coinage  for  Ireland,  61  ;  Debts 
— father,  brother  and  sister 
paid,  64 

Estate  duties,  59 

Exchequer  (The  public  Treasury) 
— Ancient  Accounting  system 
of,  130 ;  Anglo-Saxon,  52  ; 
Budget,  134  ;  Chancellor  of, 
136  ;  ConsoUdated  Fund,  137  ; 
Departments  and  officials,  136  ; 
Emergency  measures,  1914,  5  ; 
Expenditures,  1688-1817,  118. 
120  ;  1688-1920,  145,  and  Bank 
of  England,  158  ;  Modern,  135  ; 
Norman  period,  53,  58  ;  Re- 
ceipts, 1688-1830,  118-121; 
1688-1920,  142  ;  Talhes,  132  ; 
Treasury,  133  ;  and  Bank  of 
England,  137 

Bills  :     First    issued,    1696, 

75,  85,  Reign  of  William  III, 
86,  158 ;  Largely  superseded 
by  Exchequer  bonds  (1853), 
184  ;  and  Treasury  bills  (1871), 
11.  185 

Bonds,  184 

Order  and  Tallies,  83,  84 

,  Stop  of,  65 

Excess  Profits  Tax— See  Taxation 
Excise  Taxes  :  Introduced  from 
Holland  in  1643,  58  ;  of  Charies 
II,  72  ;  French  war  period,  121 
Expenditure,  2^  centuries  v.  six 
years,  15  ;  Character  of,  1817- 
1914,  123;  Civil — increase 
after  each  war,  120  ;  Civil 
Government,  1817-1914,  123; 
Distribution,  1833-1914,  Table, 
126  ;  Debt  charge,  increasing 
burden  after  each  war,  119; 
Debt  charge,  1817-1914,  123  ; 
Military  steadily  rises,  119, 
124,  125  ;  Principal  objects  of, 
1688-1920,     145  ;      War    chief 


cause,  77  ;  1688-1830  for  alter- 
nate periods  of  peace  and  war, 
120;  1688-1920,  15,  145;  MiH- 
tary— 1816-1914,  124  ;  1915- 
1920— Table,  15 

Exchanges,  Foreign,  Working  of, 
described,  7 

Export  Merchants,  Advances  to. 
in  1914.  9 

Extortions — Forms  of,  practised 
by  early  kings,  60 

Factor,  The  King's,  152 

Fairs,  Anglo-Saxon  and  Norman, 
51 

Farm  (or  Ferme),  Farming  cus- 
toms, how  done  and  why,   150 

Federal  Reserve  Banks — U.S. — 
carry  ultimate  specie  reserves 
of  all  banks,  34 

Ferme — See  Farm 

Feudal  system  :  Aids,  53  ;  Anglo- 
Saxon,  49  ;  Knights  service, 
53  ;  Norman  sj^stem  of  land 
tenure,  53 

"  Finance  Accounts,"  58,   141 

,  National  :  Dutch  experi- 
ence a  valuable  asset  to  William 
III,  80 ;  Germs  of  modem 
financing  methods  found  in 
early  practice,  58 

Financial  conditions  in  July, 
1914,  4 

Fines,  54,  Extortionate,  60 

Fiscal  system  to-day  :  Account- 
ing of&cers,  140  ;  Bank  of 
England,  137  ;  Bank  of  Ire- 
land, 138;  Budget,  134; 
Exchequer,  135  ;  Chancellor 
and  Aids,  136 ;  Consolidated 
Fund,  137  ;  Financial  Reports, 
141  ;     Paymaster-General,    139 

Flemish  merchants.  Loans  to 
Edward  VI.  Mary  and  Eliza- 
beth, 64,  153 

Folk-land,  50 

Foreign  investments,  5 

securities,  Mobilization  of,  20 

Forests,  The  King's,  53 

Forest  laws,  53 

Free  Trade — See  Customs,  66,  77 

Fumage — See  Taxation,  59 

Fund  of  credit,  88,  158 

Genoa,  Bank  of  (Ufficio  di  San 
Giorgio),  Cartulary  notes — 
Character  of  business,  154 


204 


INDEX   AND    GLOSSARY 


George,  David  Lloyd,  5 

"  Giro  payments  "  defined,   153 

,  Banco  del  (Bank  of  Venice), 

153 

Goldsmiths,  The,  155,  159 

Grants — See  Aid 

Great  Britain — See  United  King- 
dom 

Gresham,  Sir  Thomas,  King's 
factor,    152 

"  Hearth-Money,"  57 

Hereditary  revenues — See  Pre- 
rogative, 53 

Henry  II  :  Exchequer  records 
date  from  his  reign,  47 

Ill  :      The     first     king     of 

England   whose   debts   are   re- 
corded, 62 

IV,  67 

V,  63 

VIII,  60,  63,  64,  68 

"  Here-geld,"  49 

Hide — of  Land  :  A  medieval 
measure  of  land — about  100 
acres,  50 

Holden,  Sir  Edward  H.,  10  ; 
process  of  payment  for  govern- 
ment loans  described,  35 

Hearth  tax,  50 

"  Heavy  horse,"  97 

House  duty,  59 

Income,  National  :  Defined,  last 
T,  127;  1688-1817.  116,  117; 
V.  Debt  Charge,  115;  1817- 
1914,  128;    1920,  3 

tax — -See  taxation.     First 

modern,  1799,  75,  123 

Invisible  trade  balance,  5 

India,  Cost  of  war  to,  1914-1919, 

I.  17 

Inflation,  High  prices  and  bank 
credits,  43  ;  By  bank  deposit 
credit,  1914-1920,  11  ;  Methods 
of — used  to  finance  war  1914- 
1920,  11  ;  One  measure  of,  45  ; 
By   notes,   bank  and  treasury, 

II,  41  ;      Prices     v.     Physical 
volume  of  trade,  43 

Interest  :  Charge  for,  forbidden 
in  medieval  times,  62  ;  Pay- 
ment forbidden  by  Church,  62  ; 
Payments  in  lieu  of,  62,  65,  150 

"  Issue  " — English  Treasury  term 
for  "  payment  " 


Italian    Banks,    Early    corporate, 
153 


James  I,  Financial  methods  re- 
viewed, 68,  69 

II,  73 

Jews,  Taxation  of,  57 

John:   Debenture  of,  151  ;   Letter 

of  Credit  of,  152 

,  Magna  Charta  (1215),  47,  66 

Joint-stock     Banks — See     Banks, 

Joint  Stock 

Kemmerer,  E.  W.,  Physical 
volume  of  trade,  1913-1919,  43 
Kindersley,  Sir  Robert,  22,  23 
King  :  Demesne,  49 ;  Factor, 
152  ;  V.  People,  47,  48  ;  Pre- 
rogative, 53  ;  Knights  Service, 
53 

Lancaster  and  York,  Period  of, 

67 
Lands  :      Crown — See    Demesne  ; 

Taxation  of — See  Taxation 
Letter  of  Credit— A. D.  1201,  152, 

originated  in  Italy,  150 
Licence  fees — See  Taxation 
"  Light  Horse,"  97 
Lombards,  155 
Loans — See  Debt,  National 
London    Joint    City    &    Midland 

Bank,  26 
Long  Parliament  (1640-1653),  57  ; 

Post  Office  inaugurated  by,  58 
Lotteries — 5^^  also  Debt,  National 

First   in    England    (1569),    93; 

Last    (1826),   99;     Private  lot- 
teries  illegal   but    flourish,   98 ; 

State  lotteries,  97-100 
Lottery     Loans,     94 — See     Debt, 

National 

Tickets,  96 

Magna  Charta — See  Charters 

Mary,  Queen,  64 

Merchants,  Anglo-Saxon  times,  51 

Million  Bank,  88 

Mobilization  of  Foreign  Securities, 
20 

Monopolies,  60 

"  Monthly  Assessments  " — intro- 
duced by  Long  Parliament,  58  ; 
See  Taxation 

Moratorium  (1914),  7,  10 


INDEX   AND    GLOSSARY 


205 


Napoleon,  Continental  Policy — 
Result  to  England,  163 

National  Debt — See  Debt,  Na- 
tional 

Na\-y  Bills,  85,  106— See  Debt, 
National 

Newfoundland,  Cost  of  War,  1914- 
1919,  1 

New  Zealand,  Cost  of  War,  1 

Nicholson,  Prof.  J.  Shield,  39 

Norman  Period,  49 

North,  Lord,  Financial  Methods 
in  American  War,  96 

Northcote,  Sir  Stafford  H.,  128 

"  Nova  Custuma,"  i.e.,  New  Cus- 
toms— See  Customs,  56 

"  Omnium,"  96 

Paterson,  William,  proposes  or- 
ganization of  Bank  of  England, 
157 

Paymaster-General,  139 

Peel,  Sir  Robert,  brings  about 
separation  of  Banking  and 
Issue  departments  of  Bank  of 
England,  171 

"  People,"  Definition  of  term  as 
used  herein,  47 

V.  King,  47 

Peruzzi,  Italian  bankers,  ruined  by 
Edward  III,   153 

Personal  Property,  Taxation, 
dates  from  reign  of  Edward 
III,  58 — See  Taxation 

Pipe  Rolls  ("  Rolls  of  account  " 
in  text),  47 

Pitt,  William,  The  younger  :  Chan- 
cellor of  Exchequer,  1784,  106  ; 
Competitive  bidding  for  loans 
and  army  supplies  inaugurated 
by,  107  ;  Income  tax,  modern, 
originated  by  in  1799,  75  ; 
Methods  used  in  financing 
French  War,  108,  110,  161; 
Navy  Bills  funded  by,  106  ; 
Recalled  in  1804,  HI;  Death 
of,  1806,   111 

Plantagenets,      Development      of 

Constitution  under,  66 
Pole,  William  de  la,  153 
Poll-taxes,  57  ;    of  Charies  II,  70 

— See  Taxation 
Post  Office,  Introduced  by  Long 
Parliament,  58 


Pre-emption — See  Prerogative,  54 
Prerogative,    King's,    53 ;     Aids, 

53  ;  Benevolences,  54  ;  Bona 
Vacantia,  54  ;  Coinage,  54  ; 
Contributions,  54  ;  Demesne, 
49,    53  ;      Estates,    unclaimed, 

54  ;  Estrays,  54  ;  Extortions, 
54  ;  Feudal  Aids,  53  ;  Fines, 
54  ;  Fish,  large,  54  ;  Forests, 
53  ;  Forest  laws,  53  ;  Idiots, 
Custody  of,  54  ;  Loans,  Com- 
pulsive, 54  ;  Monopolies,  60  ; 
Knight's  service  {See  also  Scut- 
age),  53  ;  Pre-emption,  54  ; 
Prisage  of  wine  {See  New 
Customs),  55  ;  Purveyance, 
Anglo  -  Saxon,  50  ;  Norman 
times,  54  ;  Queen's  Gold,  54  ; 
Treasure  trove,  54  ;  Trinoda 
Necessitas,  49  ;  Wrecks,  54  ; 
Surrendered  by  Charles  II,  72 

Prices,  Index  Number,  1913-1919, 
45 

and    Bank    Credits,    43,    v. 

Physical  Volume  of  Trade,   43 

Public  Debt — See  Debt,  National  • 

Expenditure — See  Expendi- 
ture 

Purveyance  :  Anglo-Saxon,  50  ; 
Norman  times  to  1688,  55 ; 
See  Prerogative 

Queens'  gold,  54 

Quotations  :  Bank  of  England 
Stock,  1697-1919,  188;  Con- 
sols, 1697-1919,  188;  War 
issues,  1910-1919,  190 

Ransom  :  King  Richard's,  59 — 
See  also  Feudal  Aids  under 
Prerogative 

Reserves  :  Specie,  1913-1919— 
Table,  44 

Restriction  Act,  163 

Revenue — National,  118;  Aver- 
age annual,  1688-1830,  121  ; 
At  historic  periods,  1688-1920, 
142 — See  Debt,  Prerogative, 
Taxation 

Revolution  of  1688,  dividing  hne 
between  old  and  new  England, 
48,  74 

Richard  I,  Income  tax  first  levied 
by,  59 

II,  64,  66 


2C6 


INDEX   AND    GLOSSARY 


"  Scrip,"  97 

Scutage  ("  Escuage,"  derived  from 
"  escu  "  (French),  a  shield  ;  a 
sum  of  money  paid  in  lieu  of 
service  of  the  shield,  i.e.,  of 
knight's  service  (53)  ).  An  early 
form  of  land  tax,  57 

Ship-geld,  50 — See  Taxation 

Sinking  Funds  :  Walpole's,  101  ; 
Pitt's,  102  ;  Modem,  12,  18,  26, 
104,  186 

Social  betterment,  expenditure 
for,  125,  144 

South  Sea  Company,  history, 
purpose  and  scheme  of,  89 

Stamp  duties,  first  imposed  in 
1671,  58 — See  Taxation 

Stock  Exchange  loans,  how  pro- 
tected 1914,  9 

Stuart  and  Cromwellian  period, 
one  of  transition  from  autocracy 
to  democracy,  68 

Stuarts,  last  of  autocrats,  68 

Subsidy  :  Customs,  55  ;  A  form  of 
tax,  56 — See  Customs  ;  also 
Taxation 

Tally — (talea — a  slender  staff,  a 
rod,  stick,  stake,  bar),  132 — See 
Debt — national — unfunded,  83  ; 
"  Tallies  of  assignment,"  83  ; 
"  Tallies  of  loan,"  83  ;  Ex- 
chequer order,  83,  84 

Tariff — See  Customs,  77  ;  Reform 
of,  1842-1914,  77,  122 

Taxation  :  Aid  (Scutage)  A  form 
of  land  tax,  57  ;  Aliens,  57  ; 
Anglo-Saxon  :  trinoda  necessi- 
tas — brig-bote,  here -geld,  or 
here-fare,  burg-bote  ;  also,  dane- 
geld,  fumage  ,59,  or  hearth-tax, 
horn-geld,  49,  50  ;  Assessed 
taxes,  1785,  58  ;  Brig-bote,  49  ; 
Burg-bote  49  ;  Cards,  tax  on, 
first  introduced  during  reign  of 
Charles  I  ;  Carucage — A  medi- 
eval tax  levied  on  land  at  so 
much  a  carucate,  i.e.,  the 
quantity  of  land  that  could  be 
ploughed  by  one  plough  in  a 
season;  Customs  (1154-1688), 
55,  59  ;  Consolidated  Fund, 
1787,  137;  "Dane-geld,"  50; 
Estate  duties,  59 ;  Excess 
profits,  13,  16,  18,  59;  Excise, 
58   ;      Fumage,     59   ;       Fund, 


consolidated,  137  ;  Hearth- 
money,  50,  57,  59  ;  Here-geld, 
49 ;  House  duty,  59  ;  Income  tax 
— most  flexible,  13  ;  first  levied 
by  I^chard  I,  59  ;  first  levied 
in  modern  form  by  Pitt  in  1799, 
75,  discontinued  at  close  French 
Wars,  re-introduced  in  1843, 
123  ;  Indirect,  unknown  until 
1643,  58  ;  Jews,  57  ;  Land 
taxes,  57,  59 ;  Land-value 
duties,  59  ;  Licences,  51  ;  Laws 
in  re  must  originate  in  Com- 
mons ;  Long  Parliament 
methods,  58  ;  Marriages,  births 
and  deaths  ;  Methods  in  1817- 
1914,  122  ;  Moneyage — A  form 
of  hearth  money  originating  in 
Anglo-Saxon  times — "  by  way 
of  bounty  or  recompense  to  the 
King,  not  to  alter  or  debase  the 
coin,"  abolished  by  Henry  I  ; 
Monthly  assessments,  58  ;  Ori- 
gin of  present-day  taxes,  58  ; 
Personal  property,  57  ;  Poll- 
taxes,  57.  71  ;  Post  Office.  17, 
59  ;  Pre-emption,  54  ;  Property 
and  income,  59  ;  Scutage,  pur- 
pose for  which  it  could  be 
levied,  57  ;  Ship-geld,  50  ; 
Stamp  duties  first  imposed  in 
1671,  59  ;  Subsidy — customs, 
55  ;  tax,  56  ;  Tenths  and 
Fifteenths,  57  ;  Transfers  of 
Stocks,  17  ;  Trinoda  necessitas, 
49  ;  Of  war  wealth,  17  ;  1914- 
1920,  principle  upon  which 
based,  12  ;  Tenths  and 
Fifteenths,  57 

Tonnage  Act — 1694,  Bank  of 
England  organized   under,    157 

Trade,  physical  volume  change, 
1913-1919,  43 

Treasurer — Norman  times,  47 

Treasury,  PubUc,  23,  47,  133,  135 

Bills,    8,    11,    75,    185— See 

Debt — national 

Notes,  also  called  Currency 

Notes,  Bradbury's,  6  ;  Out- 
standing, 31st  Dec,  1919,  25, 
41 

Trinoda  necessitas,  49 

Tudor     period,     control     of     the 

crown  lost  by  the  people,  67 
Tunnage  and  poundage,   56 — See 

Customs 


INDEX  AND    GLOSSARY 


207 


Ufficio  di  San  Giorgio,   154 
Union  of  South  Africa,  cost  of  war, 

1914-1919,  1 
United  Kingdom,  cost  of  war  to, 

1914-1919,  1 
Usury — See  Interest.  1 50 

Venice,  Bank  of.      Character  of 

business,  154 
"  Vote  " — English  treasury  term 

for  appropriation,  141 

Walpole,  Robert,  Chancellor  of 
Exchequer,  101 

War  :  American  banks,  how  they 
helped  finance  world  war,  33  ; 
Boer  war,  30,  112;  Debts 
caused  by  war,  79 ;  Crimean 
war,  112  ;  Cost  cumulative, 
119;  Comparison,  1688  to  1817, 
81,  118;  Debts,  19;  1688- 
1817,  81  ;  Expenditures,  1914- 
1920,  12,  14,  15;  Income, 
1914-1920,  14  ;  Dutch,  72  ; 
French,  the  Great,  31,  financing 
described,  108-117;  Greatest 
cause  of  public  debt  and 
expenditure,  76 

1914-1920— Summary,  1-3  ; 

Banks'  part  in  financing,  33  ; 
Six  years  of  war  v.  2\  centuries, 
1,  13  ;  Conditions  in  July, 
1914,  4  ;    Emergency  measures. 


1914,  5— currency  notes,  6 ; 
clearing  house  certificates,  7  ; 
moratorium,  1914,  7  ;  protect- 
ing acceptance  market,  7  ; 
treasury  bills  issued,  8  ;  stock 
exchange  loans,  9 ;  advances 
to  exporters,  9  ;  cotton  trade 
financing,  10  ;  success  attend- 
ing these  efforts,  10  ;  Costs  and 
how  met,  11,  30,  per  cent,  from 
tax,  2,  per  cent,  from  borrow- 
ing, 2  ;  Credit  structure  and 
the  banks— Table  I,  National 
debt  V.  bank  assets,  40 ;  II, 
curency  and  deposits,  42  ;  III, 
specie  reserves,  44  ;  War  Loans, 
how  financed,  34  ;  Loans  to 
Dominions  and  Allies,  31st 
March,  1920— Table,  29 

Ways  and  means  advances  :  War 
Debt,  1914-1920,  19,  36,  39 

Wealth,  War,  taxation  of,  16 

,  National,     1914    and    1920, 

3  ;  1688-1817— See  table,  81  ; 
1817-1914,  127,  128 

WUliam  I,  67 

Ill,    coinage    restored,    61, 

65  ;  First  loans,  84  ;  Grant  for 
Ufe  denied,  48  ;  Dutch  financial 
experience  an  asset,  74  ;  Fi- 
nance (pubUc),  in  reign,  80  ; 
Lottery  loan,  93  ;  National 
debt  and  Bank  of  England 
originate  in  his  reign,  74.  75 


Printed  by  Sir  Isaac  Pitman  &  Sons,  Ltd.,  Bath,  England 
w— (1823) 


PITMAN'S 

BUSINESS  HANDBOOKS 

AN  ABRIDGED   LIST   OF   PRACTICAL    GUIDES   FOR 
::     BUSINESS  MEN  AND  ADVANCED   STUDENTS     :: 


COMPLETE  LIST  OF  COMMERCIAL   BOOKS   POST  FREE   ON  APPLICATION 


BOOK-KEEPING  AND  ACCOUNTS 

ADVANCED    ACCOUNTS.      A    Manual    of    Advanced    Book-keeping    and 
Accountancy  for  Accountants,  Book-keepers  and  Business  Men.     Edited 
by  Roger  N.  Carter,  M.Com.,   F.C.A.,   Lecturer  on    Accounting  at  the 
University  of  Manchester.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  988  pp.,  lOB.Gd.net. 
AUDITING,  ACCOUNTING  AND  BANKING.     By  Frank  Dowler,  A  C.A. 
and  E.  Mardinor  Harris,    Associate  of  the    Institute  of   Bankers.     In 
demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  328  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 
THE    PRINCIPLES    OP    AUDITING.     A    Practical    Manual    for    Advanced 
Students  and  Practitioners.     By  F.  R.  M.  de  Paula  (of  the  firm  of  De 
Paula,  Turner,  Lake  &    Co.),  F. C.A.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  224  pp., 
7s.  6d.  net. 
ACCOUNTANCY.     By  F.  W.  Pixley,  F.C.A.,  Barrister- at- Law,  Ex-President 
of  the     Institute    of    Chartered    Accountants.     In    demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt, 
318  pp.,  7s.  6<1.  net. 
AUDITORS  :    THEIR   DUTIES   AND   RESPONSIBILITIES.     By  the  same 

Author.     Eleventh  Edition.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  732  jip.,  21 S.  net. 
COST  ACCOUNTS  in  Principle  and  Practice.     By  A.  Clifford   Kidgway, 
F.C.A.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  with  40  specially  prepared  forms,  59. 
net. 
COMPANY  ACCOUNTS.     By  Arthur  Coles,  F.C.I.S.     With  a  Preface  by 

Charles  Comins,  F.C.A.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  356  pp.,  78.  Cd.  net. 
DICTIONARY  OF  BOOK-KEEPING.'  By  R.   J.   Porters.     In  demy  8vo, 

780  pp.,  7s.  Gd.  net. 
MANUFACTURING  BOOK-KEEPING  AND  COSTS.     By  George  Johnson, 

F.C.I.S.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  120  pp.,  oS.  net. 
GOLD  MINE  ACCOUNTS  AND  COSTING.     A  Pi-actical  Manual  for  Officials. 
Accountants,  Book-keepers,  etc.     By  G.  W.  Tait.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth 
gilt,  5s.  net. 
THE  ACCOUNTS  OF  EXECUTORS,  ADMINISTR.\TORS  AND  TRUSTEES. 
\Vith  a  Summary  of  the  Law  in  so  far  as  it  relates  to  Accounts.     By 
William  B.  Phillips,  A. C.A.  (Hons.  Inter,  and  Final),  A.C.I.S.    Fourth 
Edition,  Revised.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt.  150  pp.,  5s.  net. 
PRACTICAL  BOOK-KEEPING.     By  Geo.  Johnson,  F.C.I.S.     In  crown  8vo, 

cloth,  420  pp.,  6s.net. 
RAILWAY  ACCOUNTS  AND  FINANCE.  Railway  Companies  (Accounts  and 
Returns)  Act,  1911.  By  Allen  E.  Newhook,  A.K.C.  In  demy  8vo, 
cloth  gilt,  148  pp.,  5s.  net. 
DEPRECIATION  AND  WASTING  ASSETS,  and  their  treatment  in  com- 
puting annual  profit  and  loss.  By  P.  D.  Leake,  F.C.A.  In  demy  Svo, 
cloth  gilt,  257  pp.,  12a.  6d.  net 

G    w— 1 


PITMAN'S   BUSINESS   HANDBOOKS 


ACCOUNTING.     By  S.  S.  Dawson,  F.C.A.  and  R.  C.  De  Zouche,  F.C.A. 

In  demy  8vo,  doth  gilt,  290  pp.,  10s.  C'd.  net. 
MANUAL  OF  COST  ACCOUNTS.     By  Junus  Lunt,   A.C.A.    (Hons.).     In 

demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  124  pp.,  6s.  net. 

BUSINESS  TRAINING 

LLtTURES  ON  iJRITISil  C0M3IERCE,  including  Finance,  Insurance,  Business 
and  Industry.  By  the  Rt.  Hon.  Frederick  Huth  Jackson,  G. 
Armitage-Smith,  M.A.,  D.Lit.,  Robert  Bruce,  C.B.,  Sir  Douglas 
Owen,  W.  E.  Barling,  J.  J.  Bisgood,  B.A.,  Allan  Greenwell,  F.G.S., 
James  Graham.  With  a  Preface  by  the  Hon.  W.  Pember  Reeves.  In 
demy  8vo,  cloth  pilt,  295  pp.,  78.  6(1.  net. 

THE  TliEOKY  AND  PRACTICE  OF  COMjiERCE.  Being  a  Complete  Guide 
to  Methods  and  IMachinery  of  Business.  Edited  by  F.  Heelis,  F.C.I.S., 
Assisted  by  Specialist  Contributors.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  620  pp., 
with  many  facsimile  forms,  6s.  net.     Also  in  2  vols. .each,  price  3s.  6J.  net. 

THE  PRINCIPLES  AND  PRACTICE  OF  COMMERCE.  By  James  Stephen- 
son, M.A.,  M.Com.,  B.Sc.  In  demy  8vo,  cioth  gilt,  650  pp..  with  many 
facsimile  forms,  lOs.  6d.  net. 

THE  PRINCIPLES  AND  PRACTICE  OF  COMMERCIAL  CORRESPONDENCE. 
By  the  same  Author.     In  demy  8vo,  320  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 

THE  PRINCIPLES  OF  COMMERCIAL  HISTORY.  By  the  same  Aulhor. 
In  demy  8vo,  279  pp.,  7s.  6J.  neh 

THE  PRINCIPLES  AND  PRACTK  E  OF  COMMERCIAL  ARITHMETIC. 
By  P.  W.  NoRUis,  M.A.,  B.Sc.  (Hons).     In  demy  8vo,  452  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 

MODi-:RN  BUSINESS  AND  ITS  METHODS.  A  Manual  of  Business  Organiza- 
tion, Management  and  Office  Procedure  for  Commercial  Students  and 
Business  ]\I.?n.  By  W.  Campbell,  Chartered  Secrclarv.  In  crown  8vo, 
cloth,  493  pp.,  7s.  Gd.  net.     Also  in  2  vols.,  each  33.  6d.  net. 

INSURANCE 

INSURANCE.  A  Practical  Exposition  for  the  Student  and  Business  Man. 
By  T.  E.  Young,  B.A.,  F.R.A.S.  With  a  Practical  Section  on  Workmen's 
Compensation  insurance,  by  W.  R.  Strong,  F.I. A.  ;  and  the  National 
Insurance  Scheme,  by  Vvvyan  Marr,  F.F.A.,  F.I. A.  Third  Edition. 
Revised  and  Enlarged.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  440  pp.,  lOs.Gd.  rtt. 

INSURANCE  OFFICE  ORGANISATION,  MANAGEMENT,  AND  ACCOUNTS. 
By  T.  E.  Young,  B.A.,  F.R.A.S.,  and  Richard  Masters,  A.C.A.  Second 
Edition,  Revised.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  150  pp.,  58.  net. 

TALKS  ON  INSURANCE  LAW.  By  Jos.  A.  Watson,  B.Sc,  LL.B.  In 
crown  8vo,  cloth,  140  pp.,  5s.  net. 

ORGANISATION  AND  MANAGEMENT 

OFFICE  ORGANISATION  AND  MANAGEMENT.  Including  Secretarial 
Work.  By  Lawrence  R.  Dicksee,  M.Com.,  F.C.A.,  and  H.  E.  Blain. 
Late  Tramways  Manager,  County  Borough  of  West  Ham.  Fourth  Edition, 
Ri^vised.      In  d-my  8yo,  tlolh  pilt,  314  pp..  7s.  fi;l.  net. 

COUNTING  HOUSE  AND  FACTORY  ORGANISATION.  A  Practical  Manual 
of  Modern  Methods  apphcd  to  the  Counting  House  and  Factory.  By 
J.  CiLMOUR  Williamson.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  182  pp.,  63.  net. 


PITMAN'S   BUSINESS   HANDBOOKS 


FILING    SYSTE3IS.     Their    Principles    and    their    Application    to    Modern 

Oflice  Requirements.     By  Edward  A.  Cote.     In  crown  8vo,  cloth  gilt, 

200  ],]•>.  v.'ith  il!ustratious,  2s.  6(1.  net. 
INDUSTRIAL  TllAFFIC  MAiNAGEJLENT.     By  Geo.  B.  Lissenden.   Author 

of  "Railway  {  R>bates)  Case  Law,"  etc.,  etc.      With  a  Foreword  by  Chakles 

E.  MusGRAVE,  Secretary,  London  Chamber  of  Commerce.     In  der.iy  8vo, 

cloth  gilt,  260  pp.,  7s.  6(1.  net. 
MOTOR  ROAD  TllANSPORT  FOR  COrtDIEEClAL  PURPOSES.     By  John 

Phillimore.     With  an  Introduction  bv  Sir  H.  P.  Waybury,  K.C.M.G., 

C.B.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  216  pp.,   lt<.  6d.  net. 
THE  PSYCHOLOGY  OF  MANAGEMEiNT.    15y  L.  M.  Gilbretii.     In  demy 

8vo,  354  pp.,  7S.  6(1.  net. 
E3IPL0YMENT      MANAGEMENT.      Compiled     and     edited     by     Daniel 

Bloomfielu.     In  demv  Svo,  507  pp.,  Ss.  6tl.  net. 
LECTURES  ON  INDUSTRIAL  AD3IINISTRATI0N.     Edited  by  B.  Muscio, 

M.A.     In  crown  Svo,   cloth,  276  pp.,  6^.  net. 
OUTLINES  OF  INDUSTRIAL   ADMINISTRATION.      By  R.  O.  Herford. 

H.  T.  Hildage,  and  H.  G.  Jenkins.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  124  pp., 

6s.  net. 
INDUSTRIAL  CONTROL.      By  F.  M.  I.awson.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt, 

130  pp.,  8s.  6d.  net. 
MUNICIPAL  OFFICE  ORGANISATION  AND  MANAGEMENT.     Edited   by 

William  Bateson,  A.C.A.,  F.S.A.A.      With   contributions   by   eminent 

authorities  on  Municipal  Work  and  Practice.     In  crown  4to,  half-leather 

gilt,  wth  about  250  diagrams  and  forms,  503  pp.,  26s,  net. 
CLUBS   AND  THEIR  MANAGEMENT.     By  Francis   W.   Pixley.   F.C.A.. 

Barrister-ai-Law.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  240  pp..  78.  6d.  net. 
SOLICITOR'S  OFFICE  ORGANISATION,  MANAGEMENT,  AND  ACCOUNTS. 

By  E.  A.  Cope  and  H.  W.  H.  Robins.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  176  pp., 

with  numerous  forms,  58.  net. 
COLLIERY  OFFICE  ORGANISATION  AND  ACCOUNTS.    By  J.  W.  Innes, 

F.C  A.,  and  T.  Colin  Campbell,   F.C.I.     In  demy  Svo,  63.  net. 
DRAPERY    BUSINESS    ORGANISATION    AND    MANAGEMENT.    By    J. 

Ernest  Bayley.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  300  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 
GROCERY  BUSINESS  ORGANISATION  AND  MANAGE3IENT.     By  C.  L.  T. 

Beeching.     With  Chapters  on  Buying  a  Business,  Grocers'  Office  Work 

and  Book-keeping,  etc.,  by  J.  A.  Smart.     Second  Edition.     In  demy  Svo, 

cloth,  160  pp.,  68.  net. 
THE  HISTORY,  LAW,  AND  PRACTICE  OF  THE  STOCK  EXCHANGE.    By 

A.  P.  PoLEY,   B..A.    Barrister-at-Law ;   and  F.   H.  Cakruthers   Gould. 

Third  Edition,  revised.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt.  348  pp.,  7s.  (id.  net. 

SHIPPINQ 

SHIPPING  OFFICE  ORGANISATION,  MANAGEMENT,  AND   ACCOUNTS. 

A  comprehensive  Guide  to  the  innumerable  details  connected  with  the 

Shipping  Trade.     By  Alfred  Calvert.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  203  pp., 

with  numerous  forms,  6s.  net. 
THE  EXPORTER'S  HANDBOOK  AND  GLOSSARY.     By  F.  M.  Dudeney. 

Foreword  by  W.  Eglington,  Founder  and  Editor  of  "  The  British  Export 

Gazette."     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  254  pp.     63.  net. 
ffHE  PRINCIPLES  OF  MARINE  LAW.     (See  p.  7.) 
CASE  AND  FREIGHT  COSTS.     The  Prin' iplesof  Calculation  relating  io  the 

Cost  of,  and  Freight  on.  Sea  or  Commercial  Cases,     By  A.  W.  E.  Crosfield. 

In  crown  Svo,  cloth,  62  pp.,  29.  net. 


PITMAN'S  BUSINESS  HANDBOOKS 


BANKING  AND   FINANCE 

MONEY,  EXCHANGE  AND  BANKING,  in  their  Practical.  Theoretical,  and 
Legal  Aspects.  A  complete  Manual  for  Bank  Oihcials,  Business  Men, 
and  Students  of  Commerce.  By  H.  T.  Easton,  Associate  oj  the  Institute 
of  Bankers.  Second  Edition,  Revised.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  312  pp., 
6s.  net. 

lOKKIGxN  EXCHANGE  AND  FOREIGN  BILLS  IN  THEORY  AND  IN 
PRACTICE.  By  W.  F,  Spalding,  Certificated  Associate,  Institute  of 
Bankers,  etc.,  etc.  Third  Edition.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  227  pp., 
78.  Gd.  net. 

EASTERN  EXCHANGE,  CURRENCY  AND  FINANCE.  By  the  same  Author. 
Third  Edition.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth,  375  pp.,  with  I  coloured  and  6 
black-and-white  full-page  plates,  153.  net. 

FOREIGN  EXCHANGE,  A  PRIMER  OF.  By  the  same  Author.  In  crown 
Bvo,  cloth,   108  pp.,  3s.  6d.  net. 

PRACTICAL  BANKING.  By  J.  F.  G.  Bagshaw,  Certificated  Associate  of  the 
Institute  of  Bankers.  With  chapters  on  "The  Principles  ol  Currency," 
by  C.  F.  Hannaford,  Associate 'of  the  Institute  of  Bankers,  and  "Bank 
Booli-keeping,"  by  W.  H.  Peard,  Member  of  the  Institute  of  Bankers  in 
Ireland.      In  demv  8vo, cloth  gilt,  397  pp.,  Ts.  6d.  net. 

BANK  ORGANISATION,  MANAGEMENT,  AND  ACCOUNTS.  By  J.  F. 
Davi.s,  D.Lit.,  M.A.,  LL.B.  (Lond.).  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt.  165  pp., 
68.  net 

BILLS,  CHEQUES,  AND  NOTES.  A  Handbook  for  Business  Men  and 
Lawyers.  To^^ether  with  the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act,  1882,  the  Amending 
Act,  Bills  of  Exchange  (Crossed  Cheques)  Act,  1906,  an-l  the  Bills  of 
Exchange  (Time  of  Noting)  Act,  1917.  By  J.  A.  Slater,  B. A.,  LL.B. 
Lond.).      Third    Edition.     In    demy    8vo,    cloth   gilt,  214  pp.,   6s.  net. 

BANKERS'  SECURITIES  AGAINST  ADVANCES.  By  Lawrence  A.  Fogg, 
Certificated  Associate  of  the  Institute  of  Bankers.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth 
gilt,  120  pp.     6s.  net. 

BANKERS'  ADVANCES.  By  F.  R.  Stead.  Edited  by  Sir  John  Paget, 
K.C.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth,    144  pp.,  6s.  net. 

THE  EVOLUTION  OF  THE  MONEY  MARKET  (1386-1916).  An  Historical 
and  Analytical  Study  of  the  Rise  and  Development  of  Finance  as  a 
Centralised,  Co-ordinated  Force.  By  Ellis  T.  Powell.  LL.B.  (Lond.). 
D.Sc.  (Econ.,  Lond.),  Barrister-at- Law.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  748  pp., 
103.  6d.  net. 
SIMPLE  INTEREST  TABLES.  By  Sir  Wm.  Schooling,  K,B.E.  IncrownSvo. 
cloth  gilt,  188  pp.,  21  s.  net. 

TALKS  ON  BANKING  TO  BANK  CLERKS.  By  Harold  E.  Evans. 
Certificated  Associate  of  the  Institute  of  Bankers.  In  crown  8vo.  cloth. 
152  ])p.,  28.  6d.  net. 
DICTIONARY  OF  BANKING.  A  Complete  Encyclopaedia  of  Banking  Law 
and  Practice.  By  W.  Thomson,  Bank  Inspector.  Third  Edition, 
Revised  and  Enlarged  1919.  In  crown  4to,  half-leather  gilt,  642  pp., 
30s.  net. 

SECRETARIAL  WORK 

CHE  COMPANY  SECRETARY'S  VADE  MECUM.     Edited  by  Philip  Tovey, 

F.C.I. S.     Third  Edition.     In  foolscap  8vo,  cloth,  3s.  6d.  net. 


PITMAN'S  BUSINESS  HANDBOOKS 


SECRETARY'S  HANDBOOK.  A  Practical  Guide  to  the  Work  and  Duties 
in  connection  with  the  Position  of  Secretary  to  a  Member  of  Pailiament, 
a  Country  Gentleman  with  a  landed  estate,  a  Charitable  Institution,  with 
a  section  devoted  to  the  work  of  a  Lady  Secretary  and  a  chapter  dealing 
with  Secretarial  work  in  general.  Edited  by  H.  E.  Blain,  C.B.E.  In 
demv  8vo,  cloth  gilt,   168  pp.,  Gs.  net. 

GUIDE  FOR  THE  COMPANY  SECRETARY.  A  Practical  Manual  and  Work 
of  Reference  for  the  Company  Secretary.  By  Arthur  Coles,  F.C.I. S. 
Second  Edition,  Enlarged  and  thoroughly  Revised.  With  76  facsimile 
forms,  and  the  full  text  of  the  Companies  Acts,  19U8  and  1913,  the 
Companies  Clauses  Act,  1845,  Companies  (Foreign  Interest)  Act,  1917, 
Companies  (Particulars  as  to  Directors)  Act,  1917,  and  War  Legislation. 
In  demy  8vo,  clolh  gilt,  432  pp.,  6s.  net. 

COMPANY  ACCOUNTS.     By  the  same  Author.     (See  p.  1.) 

DICTIONARY  OF  SECRETARIAL  LAW  AND  PRACTICE.  A  Compre- 
hensive Encyclopaedia  of  Information  and  Direction  on  all  matters 
connected  with  the  work  of  a  Company  Secretary.  Fully  illustrated  with 
the  necessary  forms  and  documents.  With  Sections  on  special  branches  ol 
SecretcU'ial  Work.  Edited  by  Philip  Tovey,  F.C.I.S.  With  contributions 
by  nearly  40  eminent  authorities  on  Company  Law  and  Secretarial 
Practice,  including  :  The  Rt.  Hon.  G.  N.  Barnes,  M.P.  ;  F.  Gore-Browne, 
K.C.,  M.A.  ;  A.  Crew,  F.C.I.S.  ;  J.  P.  Eainshaw,  F.C.I.S.;  M.  Webster 
Jenkinson,  F.C.A.  ;  F.  W.  Pixley,  F.C.A.  Third  Edition,  enlarged 
and  revised.     In  one  volume,  cloth  gilt,  101 1  pp.,  42s.  net. 

THE  TRANSFER  OF  STOCKS,  SHARES,  AND  OTHER  MARKETABLE 
SECURITIES.  A  Manual  of  the  Law  and  Practice.  By  F.  D.  Head, 
B.A.  (Oxon.),  Barrister -at- Law.  Second  Edition,  Revised  and  Enlajrged. 
In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  220  pp.,  69.  net. 

THE  CHAIRMAN'S  MANUAL.  Being  a  guide  to  the  management  of  meet- 
ings in  general,  and  of  meetings  of  local  authorities,  vrith  separate  and 
complete  treatment  of  the  meetings  of  pubUc  companies.  By  Gurdon 
Palin,  Barrister-at-Law.  and  Ernest  Martin,  F.C.I.S.  In  crown  Svo, 
cloth  gilt,  192  pp.,  3s.  6d.  net. 

HOW  TO  TAKE  MINUTES.  Edited  by  Ernest  Martin,  F.C.I.S.  Secon-l 
Edition,  Revised  and  Enlarged.    In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  130  pp.,  2s.  6'J. 

WHAT  IS  THE  VALUE  OF  A  SHARE  1  Tables  for  readily  and  correctly 
ascertaining  (1)  the  present  value  of  shares  ;  and  (2)  what  dividends  should 
be  paid  annually  to  justify  the  purchase  or  market  price  of  shares.  By 
D.  W.  RossiTER.     In  demy  Svo,  Ump  cloth.   20  pp.,  2s.  6d.  net. 

PROSPECTUSES^ :  HOW  TO  READ  AND  UNDERSTAND  THEM.  By 
Philip  Tovey,  F.C.I.S.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth,  109  pp.,  5s.  net. 


INCOME  TAX 

INCOME  TAX  AND  SUPER-TAX  PRACTICE.  Incorporating  the  Consohda- 
tion  Act  of  191S  and  the  Finance  Acts,  1919  and  1920.  Fourth  Edition. 
Bv  W.  E.  Snelling.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  15s.  net. 

INCOME  TAX  AND  SUPER-TAX  LAW'  AND  CASES.  A  Practical  Exposi- 
tion of  the  Law,  for  the  use  of  Income  Tax  Officials,  Solicitors,  Accountants, 
etc      Fourth  Edition  (in  the  press).     By  W.  E.  Snelling. 

COAL  MINES  EXCESS  PAYMENTS,  Guarantee  Payments  and  Le\aes  for 
Closed  Mines.  By  W.  E.  Snelling.  Demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  176  pp., 
128.  6d.  net. 


PITMAN'S  BUSINESS  HANDBOOKS 


EXCESS  PROFITS  (lucludiug  I-xcoss  31incral  Kights)  DUTY,  and  Levies 
under  tbo  MuniJious  of  War  Acta.  Incorporating  the  Proviiious  of  tho 
Income  Tax  Acts  made  applicable  by  Sl.Uute  and  by  Regulation,  the 
provisions  of  the  Finance  Act,  1920,  and  also  the  Regulations  of  the 
Commissioners  of  Inland  Revenue,  and  of  the  Minister  of  Munitions. 
By  W.  E.  Snelling.  Sixth  Edition,  Revised  and  Enlarged.  In  demy 
8vo,  cloth  gilt,  516  pp.,  21s.  net. 

SUPER  TAX  TABLES.     By  G.  O.  Parsons.     16  pp..  Is.  net. 

FCONQA'uCS 

l-;CONOMIC  GEOGRAPHY.     By  J.  McFarlane.  xM.A..  M.Com.     In  deraySvo, 

cloth   gilt,   5GS  pp.,  with  18  illustrations,  iGs.  6d.  net 
TilE   PRLXCil'LE..    OV   Et'OXOllIC   GEOiiRAPllV.     By   R.    N.    Rudmoss 

Brov/n,  D.Sc,   Lecturer  in  Geography  in  the    University  of  Sheffield.     In 

demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  223  pp.,  10s.  6d.  net. 
OUTLINES  OF  THE  ECONOMIC  HISTORY   OF  ENGLAND.     A  Study  in 

Social   Developn;ent.     By   H.   O.   Meredith,   M.A.,   jM  Com.,    Fellow  of 

Kind's  College,  Cambridge.     In  demy  8vo.  cloth  gilt.  376  pp.,  7s.6d.net. 
THE    HISTORY    AND    ECONOMICS    OF    TRANSPORT.       By    Adam    W. 

KiRKALDY,  M.A.,  B.Litt.,  Oxford;    M.Com.,  Birmingham;   and  Alfred 

Dudley  Evans.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  348  pp.,  los.    net. 
THE  ECONOMICS  OF  TELEGRAPHS  AND  TELEPHONES.     By  John  Lee. 

M.A.,  Traffic  Manager,  Post  Office  Telegraphs.      Id  crown  Svo,  cloth  gilt, 

92  pp.,  28.  0(1.  net. 
INDUSTRY  AND  FINANCE.     (Supplementary  Volume.)     Edited  by  Adam 

W.  KiRKALDY,  M.A.,  B.Litt.,  M.Com.    Deals  with  the  results  of  inquiries 

arranged  by  the  Section  of  Economic  Science  and  Statistics  of  the  British 

Association.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth,  5s.  net. 
TALKS  WITH  WORIiERS.    On  Wealth,  Wages  and  Production.     In  crown 

8vo.,  124  pp,,  limp  cloth,     2s.  net. 

ADVERTISING  AND  SALESMANSHIP 

THE  CSAFl^  OF  SILENT  SALESMANSHIP.  A  Guide  to  Advertisement 
Construction.  By  C.  Maxwell  Tregurtha  and  J.  W.  Frings.  Size. 
6J  in.  bv  9J  in.,  cloth,  98  pp.,  v/ith  illustrations.     5s.  net. 

THE  NEW'  BUSINESS.  A  Handbook  deahng  with  the  Principles  of  Adver- 
tising, Selling,  and  Marketing.  By  Harry  Tipper,  President,  Advertising 
Men's  League,  New  York.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  406  pp.,  8s.  6d.  net. 

SALESMANSHIP.  By  W  A.  Corbion  and  G.  E.  Grimsdale.  In  crown 
Svo,  cloth,  186  pp..  2s.  6d.  net. 

PRACTICAL  SALESMANSHIP.  By  N.  C.  Fowler,  Junr.  In  crown  Svo. 
337  i-ii.,  7s.  6d.  not. 

COMMERCIAL  TRAVELLING.  By  Albert  E.  Bull.  In  crown  Svo.  clotb 
gilt.  174  pp.,  38.  6d.  net. 

THEORY  AND  PRACTICE  OF  ADVERTISING.  By  W.  Dill  Scott,  Ph.D. 
In  large  crown  Svo,  c!olh,  with  61  illustrations,  240  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 

THE  PSYCHOLOGY  OF  ADVERTISING.  By  the  same  Author.  In  large 
crown  Svo,  cloth,  with  67  illustrations,  282  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 

ADVERTISING  AS  A  BUSINESS  FORCE.  By  P.  T.  Cheringxon.  In  demy 
Svo,  cloth.  586  pp..  8s.  6d.  net. 

HOW  TO  ADVERTISE.  By  G.  French,  Editor  of  the  "Advertising  News." 
In  crown  Svo.,  8s.  6d.  net. 

THE  3IANUAL  OF  SUCCESSFUL  STOREKEEPING.  By  W.  A.  Hotchkin. 
In  demy  Svo,  298  pp.,  8s.  6d.  net. 


PITMAN'S   BUSINESS   HANDBOOKS 


ADS.  AND  RALES.     By  Herbert  N.  Casson.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth,  167  pp. 

8s.  6(1.  net. 
THE  PRINCIPLES  OF  PRACTICAL  PUFjLICITY.     By  Truman  A.  de  Weese. 

In  large  crowTi  8vo,  cloth,  with  43  illustrations,  266  pp.,  78.  6d.  net. 

LAW 

MERCANTILE  LAW.  By  J.  A.  Slater,  B.A..  LL.B.  A  practical  exposition 
for  Law  Students,  Business  Men,  and  Advanced  Classes  in  Commercial 
Colleges  and  Schools.  Fourth  Edition.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  464  pp., 
7S.  6d.  net. 

COM^ANiES  AND  COMPANY  LAW.  Together  with  the  Companies  (Con- 
solidation) Act,  1908,  and  the  Act  of  1913.  By  A.  C.  Connrll,  LL.B. 
(Lond.),  of  the  Middle  Temple,  Barrister- at- Law.  Second  Edition, 
Revised.     In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gUt,  348  pp.,  6s.  net. 

COMPANY  CASE  LAW.  By  F.  D.  Head,  B.A.  (Oxon.),  Barrister-at-Law. 
In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  314  pp.,  7s.  6d.  net. 

THE  LAW  OF  CARlUAGt.  By  J.  E.  R.  Stephens.  B.A.,  of  the  Middle 
Temple,  Barrister-ai-Law.     In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  340  pp.,  53.  net. 

THE  LAW  RELATING  TO  THE  CARRIAGE  BY  LAND  OF  PASSENGERS, 
ANIMALS,  AND  GOODS.  By  S.  W.  Clarke,  Barnster-al-Law.  In 
demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,   350  pp.,  7s.  Cd.  net. 

INCOME  TAX  AND  SITKR-TaX  LAW  AND  CASES.     fSce  p.  5.) 

THE  LAW  RELATLNG  TO  SECRET  COMMISSIONS  AND  BRIBES  (Christ- 
mas Boxes,  Gratuities,  Tips,  etc.)  ;  The  Prcivention  of  Corruption  Acts, 
1906  and  1916.  By  Albert  Crew,  Barrister-at-Latv  ;  Lee  Prizeman  of 
Gray's  Inn.  Second  Edition.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  252  pp.,  lOs.  6d. 
net. 

BANKRUPTCY,  DEEDS  OF  ARRANGEMENT,  AND  BILLS  OF  SALE.  By 
W.  Valentine  Ball,  M.A.,  and  G.  Mills,  B.A.,  Bcirrisicrs-at-Law. 
Third  Edition,  Revised  in  accordance  with  the  Bankruptcy  and  the  Deeds 
of  Arrangement  Acts,  1914.      In  demy  8vo,  S64  pp.,  5s.  net. 

PRINCIPLES  OF  MARINE  LAW.  By  Lawrence  Duckworth,  Barrister- 
ai-l.aii).  Third  Edition,  Revised.  In  demy  Svo,  about  400  pp. 
7s.  U.  net. 

GLIDE  TO  THE  LAW  OF  LICENSING.  The  Handbook  for  all  Licence- 
holders.  By  J.  Wells  Thatcher,  Barrister-at-Law.  In  demy  Svo, 
cloth  gilt,  200  pp.,  6s.  net. 

RAILWAY  (REBATES)  CASE  LAW.  By  Geo.  B.  Lissenden.  In  demy 
Svo,  cloth  gilt.  450  pp.,   lO."*.  Gd.  net. 

PARTNERSHIP  LAW  AND  ACCOINTS.  By  R.  W.  Holland,  O.B.E., 
M.A.,  M.Sc,  LL.D.,  Barrister-at-Law.  In  demy  Svo,  cloth  gilt,  159  pp., 
6s.  net. 

THE  LAW  OF  CONTRACT.  By  the  same  author.  In  demy  Svo,  cloth, 
123  pp.,  5s.  net. 

THE  LAW  RELATING  TO  THE  CHILD  :  Its  Protecllon,  Educatloii,  and 
Employment.  With  Introduction  on  the  Laws  of  Spain,  Germany, 
France  and  Italy  ;  and  Bibliography.  By  the  same  author.  In  demy 
Svo,  166  pp.,  5s.  net 

GUIDE  TO  THE  REGiSTR.4TI0N  OF  BUSINESS  NA3IES  ACT,  1916.  By 
Kenneth  Brown,  Solicitor.     In  crown  Svo,  paper  boards,  l3.  net. 

CONVEYANCING.     Bv  E.  A.  Cope.     In  crown  Svo,  cloth,  206  pp.,  Ss.  6d.  net. 

WILLS,  EXECUTORS,  AND  TRUSTEES.  By  J.  A.  Slater,  B.A.,  LL.B. 
With  a  chapter  on  Intestacv.     In  foolscap  Svo,  cloth,  122  pp.,  2s.  6d.  net. 

INHABITED  HOUSE  DUTY.  'By  W.  E.  Snelling.  In  demy  Svo,  cloth 
gilt,  356  pp.,  129.  6d.  net. 


PITMAN'S   BUSINESS  HANDBOOKS 


THE  LAW  OF  liEPAIRS  AND  DILAPIDATIONS.     By  T.  Cato  Worsfold, 

M.A.,  LL.D.     In  crown  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  101  pp.,  3s.  6(1.  net. 
THE  LAW  OF  EVIDENCE.     By  W.  Nembhard  Hibbert,  LL.D.   Barrister- 

at-La:.'.     Tliird  Edition,  Revised.     In  crown  8vo,  120  pp.,  7s.  6(1.  net. 
THE  LAW  OF  PROCEDURE.      By  the  same  Author.     In  demy  8vo.  cloth 

gilt,  122  pp.,  5s.  net. 
BILLS,  CHEQUES,  AND  NOTES.     (See  page  4  ) 
THE   HISTORY,   LAW,    AND   PRACTICE   OF  THE    STOCK   EXCHANGE. 

(See  page  3  ) 

BUSINESS  REFERENCE   BOOKS 

BUSINESS  MAN'S  ENCYCLOPAEDIA  AND  DICTIONARY  OF  COMMERCE. 

A  reliable  and  comprehensive  work  of  reference  on  all  commercial  subjects, 
specially  designed  and  written  for  the  busy  merchant,  the  commercial 
student,  and  the  modern  man  of  affairs.  Edited  by  J.  A.  Slater,  B.A., 
LL.B.  (Lond.)  Assisted  by  upwards  of  50  specialists  as  contributors. 
With  numerous  maps,  illustrations,  facsimile  business  forms  and  legal 
documents,  diagrams,  etc.  In  4  vols.,  large  crown  4to  (each  450  pp.), 
cloth  gilt,  l\  4s.  Od.  net. 

BUSINESS  MAN'S  GUIDE.  Seventh  Revised  Edition.  With  French,  German, 
Spanish  and  Italian  equivalents  for  the  Conmierrial  Words  and  Terms. 
Edited  by  J.  A.  Slater,  B.A.,  LL.B.  (Lond.).  The  work  includes  over 
2,000  articles.     In  crown  8vo,  c'olh,  520  pp.,  6s.  6il.  net. 

COMMERCIAL  ARBITRATIONS.  By  E.  J.  Parry,  B.Sc,  F.I.C,  F.C.S. 
An  invaluable  guide  to. business  men  who  are  called  upon  to  conduct 
arbitrations.     In  crown  8vo,  cloth  gilt,  3s.  6(1.  net. 

PERSONAL  EFFICIENCY  IN  BUSINESS.  By  E.  E.  Purington.  In  crown 
8vo,  cloth  gilt,  341  pp.,  7s.  6i!.  net. 

DICTIONARY  OF  COMMERCIAL  CORRESPONDENCE  IN  SEVEN  LAN- 
GUAGES :  ENGLISH,  FRENCH,  GERMAN,  SPANISH,  ITALIAN, 
PORTUGUESE  AND  RUSSIAN.  In  demy  8vo,  cloth,  718  pp.,  129.6d.net. 
Third  Edition. 

A  MANUAL  OF  DUPLICATING  METHODS  By  W.  Desborough.  In 
demy  8vo,  cloth,  90  pp.,  illustrated,  28.  6d.  net. 

COMiMON  COMMODITIES  AND  INDUSTRIES  SERIES.  Each  book  in 
crown  Svo,  cloth,  illustrated,  3s.  net.  Vo!umL"s  already  published  on 
T(!a,  Coffee,  Sugar,  Oils,  Wheat,  Rubber,  Iron  aud  Steel,  Copper,  Coal, 
Timber,  Cotton,  Silk,  Wool,  Linen,  Tobacco,  Leather,  Clays,  Paper,  Soap, 
Glass,  Gums  and  Resins,  The  Motor  Industry,  Boot  and  Shoo  Industry,  Gas 
and  Gas  Making?,  Petroleum,  Salt,  Furnidrre,  Coal  Tar,  Knitted  Fabrics, 
Zinc,  Asbestos,  Photography,  Silver.  Carpets,  Paints  and  Varnishes,  Cordage 
and  Cordage  Hemp  and  Fibres,  Acids  and  Alkalis,  Gold,  Eledricily,  Butter 
and  Cheese,  Aluminium,  The  Brllish  Corn  Trade.  Engraving,  Lead,  Stones 
and  Quarries,  Clothing  Trades  Industry,  Modern  Explosives,  Electric 
Lamp  Industry,  Perfumery,  Ice  and  Cohl  Storage,  Telegraphy  Telephony 
and  Wireless.  

BUSINESS    ORGANISATION   AND   MANAGEMENT. 

A  Monthly  Magazine  of  High  Standar(J  for  Business  Men. 
Price  Is.  6d.    Post  Free,   Is.  9d.     Annual  Subscription  18s. 

COMPLETE    LIST    POST   FREE  ON    APPLICATION 


Sir  Isaac  Pitman  &  Sons,  Ltd.,  Parker  Street,  Kingsvvay,VV.C.2 

Aud  at  Bath,  Melbourne,  Toronto  and  New  York 


UC  SOUTHERN  REG 


BDWMWiEJliTERN 

384   LI^*W 
UNIVERSTty  C      AA      000  241  946 


384   U^Ri 
UNIV^RSTTY   C 
4£i-iB£[BkELEY-A^  CALIFORNIA 


:s 


^-6-/