Skip to main content

Full text of "Exploring the linkage between strategic groups and competitive strategy"

See other formats


UNIVERSITY  OF 

ILLINOIS  L'BR^iris, 
AT  URBANA-CHAWIPAIGN 

BOOKSTACKS 


-    I 


DATE    DUE 


GAYLORD 


PRINTED  IN  U  S  A 


5 


SI 


BEBR 

FACULTY  WORKING 
PAPER  NO.  1238 


Exploring  the  Linkage  Between  Strategic 
Groups  and  Competitive  Strategy 

Avi  Fiegenbaum 
John  McGee 
Howard  Thomas 


College  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
Bureau  of  Economic  and  Business  Research 
University  of  Illinois,  Urbana-Champaign 


BEBR 


FACULTY  WORKING  PAPER  MO.  1238 
e  g  e  of  Commerce  and  Business  Administration 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Charapaign 
April  1*86 


Exploring  the  Linkage  Between  Strategi 
Grcups  3r. d  Competitive  Strategy 


A  v  i  Fiegenbaum,  Assistant 
Department  of  Business  Administration 

John  McGee 
Temple  ton  College,  Oxford 

Howard  Thomas,  Professor 
Department  of  Business  Administration 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2011  with  funding  from 

University  of  Illinois  Urbana-Champaign 


http://www.archive.org/details/exploringlinkage1238fieg 


ABSTRACT 

Since  Hunt  (1972)  coined  the  term  "strategic  groups"  in  his  study 
on  the  home  appliance  industry,  a  growing  body  of  literature,  both 
theoretical  and  empirical,  has  used  this  concept  in  different  ways  for 
different  purposes.   This  paper  reviews  existing  literature  and 
explores  the  linkage  between  strategic  groups  and  competitive  stra- 
tegy.  The  STRATEGIC  SPACE  (SSP)  concept  is  proposed  in  order  to  help 
the  resolution  of  such  issues  as  the  identification  of  strategic  groups 
and  understanding  the  dynamic  behavior  of  strategic  groups. 


INTRODUCTION 
In  the  last  decade,  the  nature  of  a  firm's  competitive  strategy 
has  been  realized  by  both  practitioners  and  academicians  as  an  impor- 
tant element  in  business  success.   Competitive  strategy  "...  involves 
positioning  a  business  to  maximize  the  value  of  the  capabilities  that 
distinguish  it  from  its  competitors"  (Porter  (1980:47)).   According  to 
this  definition,  two  major  questions  are  raised  in  competitive  stra- 
tegy analysis: 

1.  Who  are  the  firm's  competitors? 

2.  What  kind  of  strategic  decisions  should  an  organization  take 
in  order  to  position  itself  relative  to  its  competitors? 

In  economics,  an  industry  is  often  used  to  define  competitive 
boundaries.   Two  criteria  normally  define  the  boundaries  of  the 
industry:   markets  and  technologies.   The  market  criterion  (e.g., 
Caves  (1977))  includes  within  a  specific  industry  those  firms  that 
have  products  sufficiently  similar  as  to  be  close  substitutes.   This 
similarity  is  tested  by  the  cross-elasticity  of  demand.   The  tech- 
nological criterion  (e.g.,  Andrews  (1951))  focuses  upon  the  classifi- 
cation of  firms  according  to  the  similarity  of  their  production  proc- 
esses.  In  the  United  States,  the  Standard  Industrial  Classification, 
or  S.I.C.,  follows  the  market  criterion  by  defining  industries  in  pro- 
duct terms.   (See  McGee  and  Thomas  (1986)  for  a  comprehensive  dis- 
cussion. ) 

With  the  difficulties  of  satisfying  both  market  and  technological 
criteria,  and  with  the  increasing  industrial  complexity  since  World 
War  II — diversification  of  products,  participation  in  several  "indus- 
tries" and  multinational  activity — the  definition  of  the  set  of 


-2- 

competitors  for  a  given  firm  (i.e.,  the  industry)  has  become  increas- 
ingly imprecise.   To  illustrate  the  problem,  (Huff>  Thomas,  and 
Fiegenbaum  (1985))  consider  the  response  of  Walter  Wriston,  the  Chief 
Executive  Officer  of  CITICORP,  when  asked  to  identify  his  competitors: 

Sometimes  Wriston  mentions  Morgan  Guaranty...  other- 
wise, Wriston  sees  his  competition  as  being  Merrill 
Lynch,  the  American  Telephone  and  Telegraph  Company, 
Sears  Roebuck  and  company,  Prudential-Bache  and  the 
American  Express  company.   (Bennett  (1983:16)) 

These  comments  indicate  that  the  problem  of  defining  the  firm's  com- 
petitors (i.e.,  industry  or  competitive  set)  is  an  increasingly  dif- 
ficult issue  in  formulating  competitive  strategy. 

In  his  doctoral  dissertation  on  competitive  processes  in  the 
"white  goods"  industry,  Hunt  (1972)  coined  the  term  "Strategic  Group" 
(SG)  for  the  finer  classifications  that  exist  within  industries.   He 
observed  that  different  firms  in  the  industry  adopted  different  stra- 
tegies in  order  to  achieve  their  organizational  goals.   Indeed,  firms 
similar  in  their  strategic  behavior  were  clustered  into  a  strategic 
group. 

The  concept  of  strategic  groups  allows  firms  to  make  more  sense  of 
competition  in  analyzing  complex  industries  (McGee  and  Thomas 
(1985)),  in  defining  firms'  competitors,  and  in  illustrating  the  com- 
petitive positions  available  within  an  industry.   Based  on  the  concept 
of  strategic  groups,  Caves  and  Porter  (1977)  generalized  the  theory  of 
entry  barriers  (Bain  (1956),  Vernon  (1972),  Scherer  (1980))  and  devised 
the  term  "mobility  barriers."   The  theory  of  Mobility  barriers  argues 
that  barriers  not  only  protect  firms  in  a  strategic  group  from  entry 
by  firms  outside  the  industry  but  also  provide  barriers  to  firms 


-3- 

within  the  industry  shifting  strategy  positions  from  one  strategic 
group  to  another. 

Based  on  the  concepts  of  strategic  groups  and  mobility  barriers, 
Porter  (1979)  developed  a  theory  that  explains  interfirm  performance 
differences.   According  to  this  theory,  the  structure  of  strategic 
groups  (the  height  of  mobility  barriers,  number  of  strategic  groups, 
distance  between  groups,  etc.)  affects  the  process  of  rivalry  within 
the  industry  and  hence  both  the  average  profit  and  the  dispersion  of 
firms'  profits.   In  addition,  mobility  barriers  enable  some  strategic 
groups  to  maintain  persistent  performance  advantages  over  other  stra- 
tegic groups.   Thus,  the  concept  of  strategic  groups  provides  impor- 
tant frameworks  for  analyzing  competitive  strategy. 

In  the  next  section  we  review  the  literature  on  strategic  groups 
and  go  on  to  link,  the  strategic  group  concept  with  the  analysis  of 
competitive  strategy. 

STRATEGIC  GROUPS:   LITERATURE  REVIEW 
For  research  on  strategic  groups,  it  is  crucial  to  understand  what 
the  word  "strategy"  means.   Therefore,  the  first  part  of  this  section 
illustrates  some  different  approaches  which  have  been  suggested  for 
operationalizing  the  strategy  concept.   Workable  guidelines  (rather 
than  theoretical  arguments)  are  stated  to  provide  benchmarks  for  iden- 
tifying a  firm's  strategy.   In  the  second  part  of  this  section,  stra- 
tegic groups  studies  are  reviewed  from  a  number  of  relevant  perspec- 
tives and  important  findings  are  summarized. 


-4- 


Strategy 

Despite  many  studies  exploring  different  aspects  of  firms'  strat- 
egy, there  is  no  clear  consensus  on  the  word's  definition.   The  word 
"comes  from  the  Greek  strategos ,  a  'general'  which  in  turn  comes  from 
roots  meaning  'army'  and  'lead'"  (Bracker  (1980:  219)).   A  strategist 
in  Greek  literature  was,  therefore,  the  individual  who  planned  and 
managed  wars.   In  the  last  three  decades,  the  importance  of  a 
"strategist's  viewpoint"  for  running  an  organization  was  realized  by 
both  business  practitioners  and  academicians.   Chandler,  a  business 
historian,  is  one  of  the  pioneers  in  the  development  of  the  field. 
According  to  Chandler  (1962:  13)  "strategy"  is: 

...  the  determination  of  the  basic  long-term  goals 
and  objectives  of  an  enterprise  and  the  adoption 
of  courses  of  action  and  the  allocation  of  resources 
necessary  for  carrying  out  these  goals. 

Chandler  did  not  differentiate  the  processes  of  strategic  formulation 
from  the  concept  itself.   He  also  ignored  the  important  strategic  link 
between  the  firm  and  its  environment.   However,  Chandler's  study  was 
the  springboard  for  further  contributions  concerned  with  the  defini- 
tion and  the  meaning  of  the  concept.   Many  other  authors  (e.g., 
Andrews  (1971),  Ansoff  (1965),  Cannon  (1968),  Steiner  (1969),  Katz 
(1970),  Ackoff  (1970),  Paine  and  Naumes  (1974),  Glueck  (1976)),  also 
addressed  different  aspects  of  strategy.   These  include  such  perspec- 
tives as  its  breadth,  its  components,  the  characteristics  of  its 
objectives,  the  levels  of  strategy,  and  so  forth. 

Chaffee  (1985)  examined  studies  on  the  strategy  concept  and 
classified  them  into  "three  models  of  strategy."   First,  according  to 
the  linear  model,  strategy  consists  of  decisions,  actions,  and  plans 


-5- 

that  will  be  taken  by  the  firm  in  order  to  achieve  its  goals.   The 
strategy  of  firms  which  fit  this  model  is  characterized  by  changing 
markets,  products,  and  other  activities.   The  writings  of  Chandler 
(1962),  Cannon  (1968),  Andrews  (1971),  Drucker  (1974),  and  Steiner  and 
Miner  (1977)  rest  on  such  a  linear  model.   Second,  adaptive  strategy 
is  concerned  with  the  development  of  a  viable  match  between  the  oppor- 
tunities and  risks  present  in  the  external  environment  and  the  organi- 
zation's capabilities  and  resources  for  exploiting  those  opportunities' 
(Hofer  (1973:  3)).   Adaptive  strategy  tries  to  achieve  a  match  between 
the  firm  and  its  environment.   In  contrast  to  the  linear  model  the 
adaptive  model  considers  a  firm's  action  or  reaction  as  a  response  to 
the  nature  and  magnitude  of  environmental  changes  and  pressures. 
Hofer  (1973),  Hofer  and  Schendel  (1978),  Mintzberg  (1978),  Quinn 
(1980),  Gluck  et.  al  (1982)  employ  this  model.   Finally,  Chaffee  calls 
the  third  model  interpretive  strategy,  for  it  looks  at  strategy  from 
the  viewpoint  of  the  organization's  culture.   In  this  model,  strategy 
becomes  the  "orienting  metaphors  to  motivate  behavior  expected  to  pro- 
duce favorable  organizational  results"  (Chaffee  (1985:83)).   Different 
groups  and  stakeholders  can  affect  the  firm's  strategy  and,  therefore, 
good  strategy  can  be  achieved  by  fostering  sound  communication  and 
relationships  between  the  various  stakeholders.   Such  writers  as 
Pettigrew  (1977),  Van  Cauwenbergh  and  Cool  (1982),  Dirsmith  and 
Covaleski  (1983),  and  Chaffee  (1985)  emphasize  the  relevance  of  the 
interpretive  model. 

In  trying  to  find  a  workable  guideline  (rather  than  theoretical 
arguments)  to  identify  strategy,  the  following  statements  should  be 
considered: 


-6- 


(1)  Strategy  is  "a  pattern  in  a  stream  of  decisions"  (Mintzberg 
(1978:  934)).   This  view  of  strategy  stresses  the  longitudinal 
nature  of  strategic  development  and  its  internal  consistency. 

(2)  "The  decision  must  be  important  to  the  success  of  the  enter- 
prise" (Shirley  (1983:  265)).   This  statement  emphasizes  that 
only  decisions  that  can  affect  the  success  (or  failure)  of  the 
enterprise  should  be  considered  as  strategic  decisions. 

(3)  It  is  important  to  relate  strategy  to  organizational  level. 
Hofer  and  Schendel  (1978)  emphasize  four  levels  of  an  organi- 
zation that  different  strategic  questions  should  be  raised  in 
each  level.   At  the  enterprise  strategy  level,  strategy  is 
concerned  with  the  question  of  "how  can  we  maintain  the  poli- 
tical legitimacy  of  the  organizations?"  (Hofer  and  Schendel 
(1978:15)).   At  the  corporate  strategy  level,  the  question  is 
"what  set  of  businesses  should  we  be  in?"  (Hofer  and  Schendel 
(1978:  27)).   At  the  business  strategy  level,  the  question  is 
"how  to  compete  in  a  particular  industry  or  product/market 
segment."  (Hofer  and  Schendel  (1982:   27)).   And  at  the 
functional  strategy  level,  the  question  is  on  the 
"Maximization  of  resource  productivity"  (Hofer  and  Schendel 
(1978:29)). 

(4)  For  each  level  of  organizational  strategy,  four  components  of 
strategic  decisions  can  be  identified: 

1.  Scope,  that  is,  the  extent  of  the  organization's  present 
and  planned  interactions  with  its  environment. 

2.  Resource  Deployment,  that  is,  the  level  and  pattern  of 
the  organization's  past  and  present  resource  and  skill 
deployments. 

3.  Competitive  Advantage,  that  is,  the  unique  position  an 
organization  develops  vis-a-vis  its  competitors. 

4.  Synergy,  that  is,  the  joint  effects  that  are  sought  from 
the  organization's  resource  deployments  and/or  scope 
decisions"  (Hofer  and  Schendel  (1978:  25)). 

(5)  It  is  important,  as  noted  by  Mintzberg  (1978),  to  distinguish 
between  two  major  kinds  of  strategies,  intended  and  realized. 
Intended  strategy  is  an  ex-ante  concept  whereas  realized  strat- 
egy is  an  ex-post  result.   Mintzberg  suggests  that  these  two 
strategies  should  be  studied  so  that  "...the  interplay  between 
intended  and  realized  strategies  may  lead  us  to  the  heart  of 
this  complex  organizational  process"  (Mintzberg  (1978:  934)). 

In  summary,  the  five  perspectives  above  can  serve  as  a  guideline 

for  the  purpose  of  formulating  strategic  groups.   More  specifically, 


-7- 

iteras  1,  3  and  4  (longitudinal,  level  and  component,  respectively) 
define  what  may  be  called  the  Strategic  Space  (SSP).   Either  intended 


Insert  Figure  1  About  Here 


or  realized  strategy  can  be  drawn  on  this  space  (item  5).   Item  (2) 
above  emphasizes  that  strategic  decisions  are  important  to  the  success 
(or  failure)  of  the  organization.   Therefore,  the  important  dimensions 
which  define  strategic  groups  should  reflect  matters  of  salience  and 
importance  to  the  company. 

Strategic  Groups:   Review  and  Perspectives 
Since  Hunt  (1972)  coined  the  term,  both  theoretical  and  empirical 
literature  has  used  the  concept  of  "strategic  groups'"  in  different 
ways.   Researchers  in  industrial  organization  economics,  strategic 
management,  marketing,  among  others,  have  all  employed  the  concept. 
An  extensive  research  review  is  available  in  McGee  and  Thomas  (1986). 
In  this  paper  the  review  of  studies  on  strategic  groups  falls  into  the 
following  categories. 

1.  Fundamentals  of  strategic  groups  theory. 

2.  The  theory  of  strategic  structure  within  an  industry  and  firm 
performance. 

3.  Strategic  group  formation  and  the  behavior  of  firms  and 
groups  over  time. 

4.  Summary  of  the  empirical  studies  on  strategic  groups. 

5.  The  relevance  of  strategic  groups  for  competitive  strategy 
analysis. 


-8- 

Fundamentals  of  Strategic  Groups  Theory 

The  traditional  paradigm  in  the  field  of  industrial  organization 

economics  argues  that  firm  performance  is  strongly  influenced  by 

market  structure.   Market  structure  includes  elements  such  as  seller 

concentration,  barriers  to  entry  and  exit,  product  differentiation, 

industry  growth,  and  economies  of  scale  (see  Bain  (1956),  Vernon 

(1972),  Caves  (1977),  Scherer  (1980)).   The  logic  of  this  paradigm  is 

that  market  structure  influences  the  market  conduct  of  the  firms  and 

that  in  turn  determines  market  performance.   The  crucial  assumption  is 

that  all  firms  are  profit  maximizers  and  sharing  the  constraints  of 

market  structure,  will  tend  to  behave  in  the  same  way. 

Firms  in  an  industry  are  assumed  to  be  alike  in  all 
economically  important  dimensions  except  for  their 
size  (Porter  (1979;  214)). 

The  homogeneity  assumption,  which  considers  each  firms'  behavior 

(strategy)  to  be  alike,  was  the  reason  that  firm  behavior  elements 

were  ignored  in  the  structure/performance  paradigm.   A  number  of 

empirical  studies  (e.g.,  Comanor  and  Wilson  (1967),  Hall  and  Weiss 

(1967),  Collins  and  Preston  (1968),  Shepherd  (1972),  Gale  (1972), 

Bass,  Cattin  and  Wittink  (1978))  have  confirmed  that  firms'  profits  in 

an  industry  can  be  partially  explained  by  market  structure  elements. 

In  the  last  decade,  more  attention  has  been  paid  to  the  relevance 

of  firms'  behavior.   Newer  industrial  organization  (10)  paradigms 

attempt  to  integrate  more  formally  the  firm's  performance  with  its 

conduct  as  well  as  with  the  market  structure.   The  main  argument  in 

the  "behavioralist "  paradigm,  namely,  that  a  firm's  strategic  choice 

has  an  impact  on  the  firm's  performance,  brings  the  industrial 


-9- 

organization  and  strategic  management  disciplines  closer  to  each 
other.   Strategic  management  writers  argue  that  the  study  of  a  firm's 
conduct  should  be  the  primary  focus  for  research  (see  Porter  (1981a) 
for  the  contribution  of  1.0.  to  strategic  management.)   Empirical 
studies  (e.g.,  Hatten  (1974),  Patton  (1976))  have  shown  that  firm- 
level  conduct  (strategy)  variable(s)  contribute  to  the  explanatory 
power  of  the  structure/performance  paradigm. 

Investigating  the  strategic  patterns  in  the  '"white  goods"  industry, 
Hunt  (1972)  realized  that  within  the  industry,  groups  of  firms  use 
different  strategies.   Hunt  coined  the  novel  term  strategic  groups  to 
characterize  the  strategic  diversity  within  the  industry.   According 
to  Hunt  (1972;  8-16)  a  strategic  group  is  defined  as: 

A  group  of  firms  within  the  industry  that  are  highly 
symmetric  ...  with  respect  to  cost  structure,  degree 
of  product  differentiation,  degree  of  vertical  inte- 
gration, and  the  degree  of  product  diversification 
...  formal  organization,  control  systems,  and  manage- 
ment rewards  and  punishments  ...  (and)  the  personal 
views  and  preferences  for  various  possible  outcomes. 

From  an  industrial  organization  point  of  view,  the  clustering  of 

companies  into  strategic  groups  has  an  important  contribution  to  the 

structure/conduct/performance  paradigm.   The  empirical  findings  have 

shown  that  the  explanation  of  firm  performance  in  an  industry  improves 

when  strategic  group  factors  are  included  as  independent  variables 

(e.g.,  Newman  (1973)).   In  addition,  different  relationships  between 

profit  and  strategy  were  found  for  firms  in  different  strategic  groups 

(e.g.,  Hatten  (1974),  Patton  (1976)).   From  a  strategic  management 

point  of  view,  the  recognition  of  strategic  groups  within  an  industry 

has  the  important  implication  that  it  occupies  an  intermediate  level 


-10- 

between  Che  industry  and  the  firm  for  analyzing  the  nature  of  com- 
petitive strategy. 

Based  on  the  concept  of  strategic  groups,  Caves  and  Porter  (1977) 
developed  the  concept  of  mobility  barriers,  a  modification  of  the 
entry  barrier  (Bain  (1956))  idea.   Theories  about  entry  barriers  argue 
that  existing  firms  are  protected  from  new  entrants  into  the  industry 
by  such  elements  as  economies  of  scale,  product  differentiation,  and 
the  like.   The  mobility  barriers  theory  argues  that  barriers  impede 
not  only  newcomers  but  also  firms  in  the  same  industry  but  with  dif- 
ferent asset  configurations  who  might  wish  to  improve  their  relative 
strategic  positioning  by  moving  into  another  strategic  group. 

In  summary,  it  is  argued  here  that  the  strategic  groups  concept  is 
important.   More  specifically,  the  concept  is  important  in  examining 
the  structure/conduct/performance  paradigm,  the  nature  of  intra-industry 
structures  and  their  effects  on  firm  performance,  and  the  duality  of 
mobility  barriers  and  strategic  groups.   Two  topics  are  explored  in 
the  following  sections,  namely,  the  theory  of  the  strategic  structure 
within  an  industry  and  firm  performance,  and  strategic  groups  for- 
mation and  the  behavior  of  firms  and  groups  over  time. 

The  Theory  of  the  Strategic  Structure  Within 
an  Industry  and  Company's  Performance 

Porter  (1979,  1980)  presents  a  theory  of  the  determinants  of  firm 

profit  performance  based  on  the  strategic  structure  within  the 

industry.   Based  on  the  concepts  of  strategic  groups  and  mobility 

barriers,  the  theoretical  explanation  is  divided  into  the  following 

steps : 


-11- 

a)   The  configuration  of  strategic  groups  within  the  industry  has 
an  impact  on  the  overall  performance  of  the  industry.   Porter  (1979; 
218)  suggested  that  the  number  and  size  distribution  of  strategic 
groups,  the  strategic  distance   among  strategic  groups,  and  the  market 
interdependence  among  groups  are  the  major  variables  which  define  con- 
figuration.  The  greater  the  number  of  strategic  groups,  when  most  of 
the  groups  have  equal  size,  then  the  greater  is  the  rivalry  among  them 
or  the  greater  is  the  chance  of  tacit  collusion.   On  the  other  hand, 
when  few  strategic  groups  exist,  and  the  size  distribution  of  these 
groups  is  not  equal,  this  structure  gives  advantage  to  the  large  stra- 
tegic groups;  tacit  collusion  is  not  expected. 

It  is  also  expected  that  the  greater  the  distance  among  strategic 
groups,  the  more  difficult  will  be  any  tacit  collusion,  and  the  more 
likely  strong  rivalry  will  exist  within  the  industry. 

Market  interdependence  indicates  the  degree  to  which  different 
strategic  groups  compete  for  the  same  customers.  It  is  expected  that 
with  a  high  level  of  interdependency ,  competition  will  not  only  be 
intense  but  varied  in  form  reflecting  the  diverse  asset  structures  of 
competitors. 

Hergert  (1983)  developed  statistical  measures  for  the  strategic 
groups  configuration.   He  was  able  to  show  that  some  of  the  expected 
relationships  between  strategic  groups  configurations  and  industry 


Harrigan  (1985)  and  Hergert  (1985)  have  measured  strategic 
distance  in  terms  of  the  distance  (difference)  between  the  centroids 
of  the  strategic  groups  (defined  in  terms  of  the  relevant  and  impor- 
tant strategic  variables). 


-12- 

profits  were  in  the  expected  direction  (as  were  hypothesized  by  Porter 
(1979)). 

b)  The  location  of  the  strategic  group  relative  to  other  strate- 
gic groups  may  convey  advantages  or  disadvantages  to  the  group's 
members.   There  are  several  possible  reasons.   First ,  some  types  of 
strategies  are  more  suited  to  market  conditions  than  others,  and  can 
result  in  superior  performance.   Thus,  firms  which  belong  to  better 
performing  strategic  groups  will  have  the  opportunity  to  achieve  above 
industry  average  profit.   Second,  each  strategic  group  has  a  different 
ability  to  protect  itself  from  competitive  firms  in  other  strategic 
groups  (Caves  and  Porter  (1977)).   Strategic  groups  with  significantly 
superior  mobility  barriers  are  better  able  to  exploit  profit  oppor- 
tunities.  McGee  (1985)  and  McGee  and  Thomas  (1986)  categorized  the 
mobility  barriers  into  three  classes:   market,  supply  and  firm-specific 
strategic  variables.   In  addition,  mobility  barriers  may  also  arise 
from  what  Lippman  and  Rumelt  (1981)  called  the  concept  of  "uncertain 
iraitability , "  meaning  that  even  if  a  firm  wants  to  replicate  the  stra- 
tegy of  firms  in  a  superior  strategic  group,  it  may  fail  because  of 

its  uncertainty  about  how  to  imitate  and  implement  that  strategy  in 
practice.   Third,  the  degree  to  which  firms  in  the  same  strategic 
group  compete  amongst  each  other  can  also  affect  the  average  profit  of 
the  group  relative  to  other  groups.   When  firms  in  the  same  strategic 
group  try  to  improve  their  position,  other  firms  may  retaliate,  and 
the  potential  profit  of  the  strategic  group  as  a  whole  may  decrease. 

c)  The  location  of  the  firm  within  the  strategic  group  affects 

the  firm's  performance.   The  rationale  for  this  proposition  is  given  by 
Porter  (1979;  218-219): 


-13- 


While  firms  following  similar  strategies  will  likely 
be  of  comparable  scale,  scale  differences  may  work  to 
the  disadvantage  of  smaller  firms  in  the  group  where 
there  are  aspects  of  the  strategy  (e.g.,  captive  dis- 
tribution) subject  to  economies  of  scale. 

d)   The  ability  of  the  firm  to  implement  its  strategy  will  also 
affect  the  firm's  performance.   Some  firms  are  better  organized, 
managed,  controlled  than  others,  which  will  give  them  superior  perfor- 
mance (see  Galbraith  and  Nathanson  (1978)  for  a  comprehensive 
discussion  on  strategic  implementation). 

In  summary,  the  concept  of  strategic  groups  was  developed  by 
Porter  in  order  to  structure  a  theory  of  interfirm  performance  dif- 
ferences.  Four  elements  are  the  fundamentals  of  this  theory.   First, 
the  configuration  of  strategic  groups  (e.g.,  the  number  of  groups  and 
the  size  distribution  of  groups)  has  an  impact  on  the  overall  perfor- 
mance of  the  industry.   Second,  the  location  of  a  strategic  group 
relative  to  other  industry  level  strategic  groups  may  have  performance 
implications  for  group  members.   Third,  the  location  of  the  firm 
within  the  strategic  group  may  influence  its  performance.   Fourth,  the 
ability  of  the  firm  to  implement  its  strategy  may  affect  its  perfor- 
mance. 

Strategic  Groups  Formation  and  the  Behavior  of  Firms  and  Groups 
Over  Time 

Why  and  how  do  strategic  groups  form?   How  do  they  behave  over 
time?   How  do  firms  move  within  and  between  groups?   These  questions 
have  not  yet  attracted  much  attention. 


-14- 

The  Formation  of  Strategic  Groups: 

A  necessary  condition  for  the  formation  of  strategic  groups  is  that 
companies  within  an  industry  behave  differently.  Economics  and  organi- 
zation theories  suggest  several  rationales  for  this  phenomenon. 

a)  Different  firms  have  different  goals:   profit  maximizing 
(Stigler  (1964)),  revenue  maximizing  (Baumol  (1967)),  growth  maximizing 
(Morris  (1964),  Williamson  (1966))  or  management  utility  maximizing 
(Williamson  (1963). 

b)  Even  if  firms  compete  for  the  same  goal,  different  strategies 
can  be  used  to  achieve  those  goals.  Hergert  (1983:  II-2)  developed 
an  industry  level  mathematical  model  which  assumed  that  member  firms 
maximize  the  same  goals  (utility  function)  and  yet  found  that  they 
achieved  them  through  the  use  of  markedly  different  strategies.  This 
implies  that  firms  within  industries  may  adopt  dissimilar  strategies 
even  when  they  are  trying  to  achieve  similiar  goals. 

c)  Firms  make  different  assumptions  about  the  future  potential  of 
the  industry  (Porter  1980;  49),  which  may  lead  them  to  behave  dif- 
ferently. 

d)  Firms  have  different  skills  and  resources.   For  example,  new 
entrants  don't  have  the  same  experience  as  established  firms 
(Henderson  (1979)),  giving  the  latter  firms  a  potential  competitive 
advantage  over  new  entrants.   To  compete  effectively,  the  new  entrants 
will  look  for  other  competitive  dimensions:   unique  skills  or  resources 
in  marketing,  production,  research  and  development,  and  the  like. 

e)  Changes  in  the  industry  environment — growth  or  decline  in 
demand,  technical  change  or  whatever — will  affect  different  firms  in 
different  ways. 


-15- 

Firm-level  and  Group-level  Behavior  Over  Time: 

To  understand  Che  dynamic  characteristics  of  strategic  groups 
requires  two  levels  of  investigation:   the  firm  and  group. 

Firm  level:   The  theory  of  strategic  groups  argues  that  firms 
within  an  industry  can  be  clustered  into  groups.   Most  studies  in  the 
area  of  strategic  groups  either  specify  current  strategic  groups  or 
investigate  the  relationship  between  performance  and  strategy  for  dif- 
ferent strategic  groups.   However,  it  is  argued  here  that  strategic 
group  studies  can  contribute  to  our  understanding  of  the  firm's  strate- 
gic behavior.   More  specifically,  once  strategic  groups  are  iden- 
tified, and  firms  make  sense  of  the  strategies  of  close  competitors, 
it  is  likely  that  strategic  group  members  (firms)  will  follow  similar 
strategies  over  time.   Several  explanations  can  be  offered  to  support 
this  viewpoint.   First,  firms  in  the  same  strategic  group  have  similar 
assumptions  about  the  future  potential  of  the  industry  (Porter 
(1980)).   Secondly,  strategic  group  members  have  similar  goals  and  the 
skills  that  are  required  to  achieve  these  goals.   If  there  is  either 
an  external  or  an  internal  change  in  the  industry,  all  strategic  group 
members  are  expected  to  react  in  the  same  way  (Caves  and  Porter  (1977: 
251)).   This  argument  is  consistent  with  the  adaptive  model  of  firm's 
strategy  (Chaffee  (1985)).   Moreover,  taking  the  adaptive  model  one 
step  further,  firms  within  the  same  strategic  group  have  similar 
mechanisms  for  strategic  adaptation,  and  these  adaptation  mechanisms 
differ  across  strategic  groups.   Even  if  a  firm  is  not  "happy"  with 
its  current  strategy,  it  is  not  easy  to  move  to  a  more  successful 
strategic  group.   Such  strategic  barriers  such  as  mobility  barriers 


-16- 

(Caves  and  Porter  (1977),  McGee  and  Thomas  (1986)),  uncertain  inst- 
ability (Rumelt  (1981))  and  inertia  (Huff,  Thomas  and  Fiegenbaum 
(1985))  may  induce  firms  to  remain  in  the  same  strategic  group.   Three 
empirical  studies  on  firm  movement  among  strategic  groups  support  this 
proposition.   Oster  (1982)  observed  that  few  firms  moved  between  the 
two  strategic  groups  she  defined  (as  below  and  above  the  industry 
average  of  advertising  over  last  year  sales).   Fiegenbaum  and  Primeaux 
((1983),  (1985))  also  found  low  level  of  firm  movement  among  strate- 
gic groups  when  strategic  groups  were  defined  in  terms  of  market 
share  and  several  other  strategic  variables. 

In  summary,  strategic  group  members  will  probably  follow  similar 
strategies  over  time.   Similarities  involving  strategic  assumptions, 
goals,  skills,  and  the  strategic  barriers  that  prevent  firms  from 
easily  moving  among  strategic  groups  explain  this  phenomenon,  and  stu- 
dies, such  as  Oster  (1982)  and  Fiegenbaum  and  Primeaux  ((1983), 
(1985))  provide  empirical  support. 

Group  level:   In  the  previous  section  it  is  argued  that  strategic 
group  members  will  follow  similar  strategies  over  time.   Therefore, 
the  composition  of  strategic  group  membership  is  most  likely  to  be  the 
same  over  time.   However,  another  important  aspect  of  strategic  group 
behavior  over  time  is  whether  or  not  the  strategic  group  as  an  entity 
will  move  toward  a  new  strategic  position  in  the  strategic  space. 

Organization  theories  argue  that  the  organization's  environment  is 
unstable  (e.g.,  Dess  and  Beard  (1984))  and  that  firms  are  trying  to 
adapt  their  strategic  behavior  to  environmental  change  (e.g.,  Miller 
and  Friesen  (1980),  Hofer  and  Schendel  (1978),  Chaffee  (1985)).   The 


-17- 

final  outcome  may  be  that  the  strategic  group  as  a  whole  will  be 
located  in  a  new  position  over  time.   This,  however,  depends  on  the 
strategic  group  members'  ability  to  differentiate  themselves  viably 
from  other  strategic  groups. 

In  addition,  the  studies  of  Kumar,  Thomas,  and  Fiegenbaum  (1984a, 
1984b)  have  looked  at  strategic  groups  from  a  different  angle  in  order 
to  identify  the  feasible  strategic  group  positions  within  the  strate- 
gic space.   These  studies  are  primarily  deductive  in  nature  and 
explore  a  fundamental  theoretical  issue;  namely,  whether  there  are 
limits  to  the  numbers  of  strategic  groups  which  may  exist  within  a 
specific  industry  context.   Using  the  notion  of  equilibrium  as  a 
benchmark,  Kumar  et  al.  (1984a)  specified  the  strategic  groups  that 
may  exist  in  equilibrium  under  "dominant  strategy"  assumptions.   The 
concept  of  dominant  strategy  assumes  that  only  firms  which  have  the 
"right  strategic  mix"  (strategy)  will  survive  the  competitive  game. 
The  weaker  firms  will  be  dominated  by  the  more  successful  firms. 
Kumar  et  al.  (1984b)  also  used  a  game  theoretic  approach  to  investi- 
gate some  other  properties  of  strategic  groups  in  equilibrium.   They 
concluded  that  in  a  monopolistic  competitive  market,  the  number  of 
strategic  groups  that  will  exist  in  equilibrium  depends  on  environmen- 
tal conditions  "if  there  are  K  uncontrollable  variables  in  the  utility 
function,  then  there  can  be  at  most  (K  +  1)  strategic  groups  in  a 
"structurally  stable  "equilibrium"  (p.  8).   (The  K  structurally 
uncontrollable  variables,  represent  the  environmental  variables  of  the 
model) . 


-18- 

These  approaches  in  strategic  group  studies  are  important  because 
they  include  the  future  as  another  important  dimension  for  strategic 
group  analysis.   They  argue  that  equilibrium  positions  represent 
viable  future  competitive  positions  which  will  emerge  as  the  industry 
evolves.   (Also  see  Camerer  (1985)  for  the  importance  of  equilibrium 
and  game  theoretic  approaches  for  "redirecting  research  in  business 
policy  and  strategy"). 

In  summary,  the  strategic  rationale  of  firms  and  the  pattern  of 
group  behavior  over  time  have  been  examined  here.   Tt  is  argued  that 
group  membership  is  likely  to  remain  stable  over  time.   On  the  other 
hand,  the  strategic  group  as  a  whole  may  be  located  in  a  new  position 
on  the  strategic  space  over  time.   Studies  by  Kumar,  Thomas,  and 
Fiegenbaum  (1984a,  1984b)  have  also  suggested  an  alternative  way  of 
examining  strategic  groups,  namely,  in  terms  of  their  future  rather 
than  past  or  present  orientation.   In  the  next  paragraph,  the  empiri- 
cal studies  on  strategic  groups  will  be  reviewed. 

Empirical  Studies  on  Strategic  Groups 

Since  Hunt  (1972)  published  his  study  on  strategic  groups  in  the 
home  appliance  industry,  several  writers  have  explored  various  impor- 
tant aspects  of  the  strategic  group  concept.   Table  1  compares  these 
studies  summarizing  them  along  the  following  dimensions: 

(*)  The  author  and  year  of  publication. 

(*)  The  level  of  strategic  grouping. 

(*)  The  component(s)  of  the  strategic  grouping. 

(*)  Intended  vs.  realized  strategic  groups. 

(*)  The  sample  in  the  study. 


-19- 

(*)  Static  vs.  dynamic  treatment. 

(*)  The  variable(s)  used  to  cluster  strategic  groups. 

(*)  The  technique  used  to  cluster  strategic  groups. 

(*)  The  definitions  of  strategic  groups. 

(*)  The  main  findings  of  each  study. 
Some  of  the  important  issues  arising  from  these  empirical  studies  are 
discussed  below.   First,  it  can  be  seen  that  existing  studies  have 
investigated  strategic  groups  at  different  strategy  levels  (column  2), 
specifically,  corporate,  business,  and  functional  perspectives. 


Insert  Table  1  About  Here 


Corporate-level  strategy  examines  the  issue  of  which  set  of  busi- 
nesses the  organization  should  develop  whereas  business-level  strategy 
addresses  the  issue  of  how  to  compete  in  a  particular  industry  or 
product/market  segment.   Nevertheless,  in  some  existing  studies  it  is 
sometimes  hard  to  differentiate  between  these  two  levels.   For  example, 
in  the  research  of  Hunt  (1972),  Newman  (1973,  1978)  and  Ramsler  (1982), 
it  is  clear  that  strategic  groups  were  formed  according  to  corporate 
level  strategy,  since  the  criterion  variables  for  grouping  were  the 
dispersion  of  the  firms'  product/market  activities.   Further,  studies 
such  as  Porter  (1979),  Oster  (1982),  Primeaux  (1983,  1985),  Ryans  and 
Wittink  (1985),  Fiegenbaum  and  Primeaux  ((1983),  (1985)),  Baird  and 
Sudharshan  (1983),  Hayes  et  al.  (1983),  implicity  identified  corporate 
level  strategy  since  the  criterion  variables  used  to  cluster  strategic 
groups  reflected  particular  aspects  of  the  entire  organization  (e.g.  , 


-20- 

investment  strategy,  advertising  strategy).   On  the  other  hand,  stud- 
ies such  as  Hatten  (1974)  and  Patton  (1976)  exemplify  strategic 
groups  specified  at  the  business  level.   This  is  because  most  of  the 
firms  in  the  brewing  industry  are  not  diversified  in  other  industries 
and  the  product  is  relatively  homogeneous.   Finally,  the  studies  of 
Frazier  and  Howell  (1983)  and  Hawes  and  Crittenden  (1984)  defined 
strategic  groups  according  to  functional  (marketing)  level  strategy. 

Second,  the  studies  have  identified  strategic  groups  according  to 
the  components  of  the  firm's  strategy  (Column  3).   Most  of  the  studies 
used  either  scope  or  resource  deployment  criteria  (see  Hofer  and 
Schendel  (1978))  but  some  of  them  used  both  these  components  (Ramsler 
(1982),  Fiol  (1984)). 

Third,  the  formation  of  strategic  groups  depends  upon  the  strat- 
egy definition  used  (i.e.,  strategy  as  intentions  (ex-ante  strategy 
formulation)  or  realizations  (ex-post  inference  of  intended  strategy) 
(Mintzberg  (1978))  Column  4).   Most  studies  have  used  the  realized 
strategy  definition  to  define  strategic  groups  by  inferring  strategic 
intent  from  ex-post  archival  financial  statement  information.   Only  two 
stud-ies,  Dess  and  Davis  (1984),  and  Hawes  and  Crittenden  (1984)  appear 
to  have  defined  strategic  groups  using  strategy  as  intentions.   They 
used  a  questionnaire  to  derive  perceptual  data  which  they  then  analyzed 
to  form  strategic  groups. 

Fourth,  many  industries  have  been  studied.  They  range  from  con- 
sumer goods  industries  to  producer  goods  industries,  and  from  single 
product  industries  to  multi-product  industries  (see  Column  5). 


-21- 

Fifth,  few  studies  have  analyzed  the  dynamic  aspects  of  strategic 
groups.   Only  Oster  (1982),  Ryans  and  Wittink  (1985),  and  Fiegenbaum 
and  Primeaux  ((1983),  (1985))  have  looked  at  some  dynamic  aspects  of 
strategic  groups  (see  Column  6). 

Sixth,  different  strategic  dimensions  have  been  used  to  cluster 
strategic  groups  (see  Column  7).   Some  of  the  authors  used  such  single 
criteria  as  market  share  (Porter  (1979),  Primeaux  (1983,  1985), 
Fiegenbaum  and  Primeaux  (1983)),  advertising  to  sales  ratio  (Oster 
(1982)),  and  security  prices  (Ryans  and  Wittink  (1985)).   Other  writers 
(e.g.,  Hatten  (1974),  Hergert  (1983))  used  multivariate  criteria. 

Seventh,  strategic  groups  have  been  identified  using  either  sta- 
tistical or  rule  of  thumb  procedures  (see  Column  8).   By  rule  of  thumb 
we  mean  that  the  writer  had  information  about  the  industries  that, 
based  with  the  information  on  the  criterion  variables,  allowed  them  to 
sort  the  firms  logically  into  strategic  groups  (e.g.,  Hunt  (1972), 
Porter  (1979),  Harrigan  (1981)). 

On  the  other  hand,  some  writers  who  used  multiple  criteria  to 
identify  strategic  groups  have  used  such  statistical  packages  as 
cluster  analysis  or  three  mode  factor  analysis  (e.g.,  Harrigan  (1985), 
Baird  and  Sudharshan  (1983),  respectively). 

Eighth,  different  strategic  groups  were  identified  in  the 
various  studies  (see  Column  9).   In  one  case  no  single  strategic  group 
was  identified  in  six  out  of  fifty  industries.   (Hergert  (1983:  111-28)) 
while  in  other  studies  many  strategic  groups  were  consistently  iden- 
tified (e.g.,  Newman  (1973,  1978),  Baird  and  Sudharshan  (1983)).   Each 


-22- 

writer  named  the  various  strategic  groups  according  to  some  properties 
that  dominated  the  strategic  group  membership. 

Finally,  the  main  conclusions  and  purposes  of  each  study  can  be 
specified.   The  main  conclusion  of  Hunt's  (1972)  study,  which  was  the 
springboard  for  the  whole  field  of  research,  was  that  strategic  group 
structure  can  be  identified  in  the  home  appliance  industry.   Other 
studies  have  reinforced  Hunt's  conclusions   in  different  industries 
and  at  different  levels  of  firm  strategy. 

Some  writers  have  investigated  the  structure/conduct/performance 
paradigm  of  industrial  organization  economics.   Writers  such  as  Newman 
(1973,  1978),  Hatten  (1974),  Patton  (1976),  Hergert  (1983),  have 
focused  on  this  aspect  of  strategic  groups.   Primeaux  (1983,  1985)  was 
able  to  show  that  different  strategic  groups  occur  at  different  stages 
of  the  investment  life  cycle.   Oster  (1982),  and  Fiegenbaum  and 
Primeaux  ((1983),  (1985))  examined,  movement  among  strategic  groups. 
The  low  level  of  movement  seen  in  these  studies  may  have  important 
implications  for  the  dynamics  of  competitive  strategy.   Yet  the  main 
studies  in  the  area  of  strategic  groups  are  'data-driven.'   That  is, 
they  identify  a  number  of  key  strategic  dimensions  drawn  from  Porter's 
(1980:127)  or  McGee  and  Thomas's  (1986)  listing  of  key  strategic 
variables  and  typically  use  cluster  analysis  with  data  bases  such  as 
COMPUSTAT  to  form  groups  of  firms  who  'cluster'  together  in  terms  of 
their  observed  strategic  behavior.   Criticisms  have  been  voiced  (McGee 
and  Thomas  (1986)  as  to  whether  the  observed  groups  made  sense  to 
managers  within  those  industries  or  other  interested  parties  such  as 
investment  analysts.   What  is  clearly  needed  Is  the  adoption  of 


-23- 

multiple  frameworks  (McGee  and  Thomas  1986)  for  better  understanding 
of  the  complexity  which  exists  in  competitive  and  often  fragmented 
service  industries.   Therefore,  it  would  seem  sensible  to  study  man- 
agers' beliefs  and  perceptions  about  competition  and  competitors  in 
order  to  identify  the  frameworks  they  use  in  competitive  positioning. 
Such  an  approach  would  clearly  identify  key  strategic  dimensions  which 
managers  perceive  to  be  important  in  formulating  strategy  and  provide 
a  better  basis  for  understanding  the  nature  of  the  strategic  dimen- 
sions which  characterize  strategic  group  formation.   Further,  it  would 
provide  insights  into  the  groupings  which  make  sense  to  managers  and 
industry  analysts  and  also  allow  comparison  to  be  made  between  the 
quantitative  'data-driven'  groupings  and  the  perceptual  groupings. 
Perhaps  themes  such  as  policy  dialogue  (Thomas  (1984))  and  triangula- 
tion  in  research  strategy  (Denzin  (1978),  Jick  (1979))  can  help 
researchers  and  managers  make  better  sense  of  the  strategic  group  con- 
cept. 

In  the  next  section,  the  linkage  between  strategic  groups  and  com- 
petitive strategy  is  explored. 

STRATEGIC  GROUPS  AND  THEIR  RELEVANCE  FOR  COMPETITIVE  STRATEGY 
Even  though  many  studies  have  explored  different  aspects  of  stra- 
tegic groups,  it  is  still  unclear  how  the  concept  of  strategic  groups 
can  be  applied  to  define  and  analyze  competitive  strategy.   Therefore, 
these  existing  research  studies  are  categorized  in  terms  of  factors 
that  are  important  for  formulation  of  competitive  strategy. 


-24- 

The  Identification  of  the  Relevant  Strategic  Dimensions 

The  identification  of  the  relevant  strategic  dimensions  used  by 
firms  in  a  given  industry  is  a  key  and  often  neglected  issue  in  some  of 
the  more  'data-driven'  studies  which  determine  strategic  groups. 
While  these  dimensions  are  extremely  important  for  making  sense  of 
strategic  groups,  they  can  also  be  used  to  assess  the  mobility 
barriers  (Caves  and  Porter  (1977))  that  protect  strategic  group  mem- 
bership from  attack  by  other  firms.   For  firms  which  are  in  the 
"superior"  performing  strategic  groups,  the  knowledge  of  the  barriers 
that  protect  them  can  aid  their  strategic  planners  in  making  decisions 
about  where  to  recommend  further  investment  to  protect  and  reinforce  those 
key  strategic  barriers.   On  the  other  hand,  a  firm  which  wants  to  move 
to  another  strategic  group  may  be  able  to  identify  a  potentially 
vulnerable  strategic  dimension  (barrier)  which  may  match  its  com- 
petitive skills  and  strengths,  hence  provide  the  firm  with  a  "gateway" 
to  entry  into  that  strategic  group. 

Researchers  need  to  develop  better  research  instruments  for  iden- 
tifying key  strategic  dimensions.   Approaches  such  as  perceptual 
mapping  in  marketing  and  other  cognitive  mapping  techniques  (Eden 
(1984))  can  help  managers  identify  their  strategic  group  maps. 
The  maps  of  industry  analysts  and  brokers  can  be  identified  through 
appropriately  designed  questionnaires  which  use  closed  ended  questions 
and  analyze  results  using  multi-dimensional  scaling  to  form  relevant 
groupings. 


-25- 

The  Identification  of  Strategic  Group  Members 

An  important  rationale  for  forming  strategic  groups  is  to  enable 
planners  to  identify  and  better  understand  the  behavior  of  com- 
petitors.  But,  who  are  the  competitors?   In  complex  industries  where 
firms  compete  on  different  strategic  dimensions,  the  definition  of  the 
set  of  competitors  for  a  given  firm  is  not  always  clear.   Porter  (1980) 
suggested  that  firms  in  the  same  strategic  group  should  recognize  each 
other  as  close  competitors  while  firms  in  different  strategic  groups  are 
less  closely  competitive.   Therefore,  knowing  strategic  group  membership 
(the  competitors)  can  aid  planners  in  understanding  the  bases  of 
competition  and  in  making  more  effective  competitive  strategy  decisions. 

For  planners  it  is  important  to  compare  groups  defined  on  the 
basis  of  industry  wisdom   (e.g.,  analysts,  managers  insights,  etc.) 
with  those  derived  from  empirical,  quantitative  studies.   Differences 
in  these  groups  may  allow  managers  and  analysts  to  review  and 
reinterpret  their  notions  of  competition. 

The  theorv  of  the  strategic  structure  within  an  industry  and 

i  -        --       -      -  --        -        -      - 

2 
interfirm  performance  differences 

Porter  (1979)  presented  a   theory  of  the  determinants  of  firm-level 

profit  based  on  the  strategic  structure  within  the  industry.   According 

to  this  theory  and  the  empirical  findings  that  partially  support  it, 

firms  following  similiar  strategies  will  tend  to  have  similiar 

performance  profiles. 


The  underlying  theory  is  explained  in  pages  10  and  11  of  this 


paper. 


-26- 

For  example,  suppose  that  two  strategic  groups  exist  within  an 
industry  (SGI,  SG2)  and  two  performance  measures,  risk  and  return,  are 
considered  by  the  companies  (see  Figure  2). 


Insert  Figure  2  About  Here 


It  can  be  seen  that  different  performance  levels  can  be  associated 
with  each  strategic  group.   This  information  may  help  strategic  plan- 
ners.  For  example,  should  firms  stay  in  the  same  strategic  group  and 
benefit  from  the  average  level  of  performance,  or  to  try  and  move  to 
another  more  attractive  strategic  group  requiring  a  different  finan- 
cial and  capital  structure  profile  but  which  provides  an  improved 
potential  average  profit  level. 
The  causal  relationship  between  structure,  strategy  and  performance 

Some  writers,  among  them  Hatten  (1974),  Patton  (1976),  Hergert 
(1983),  found  that  different  relationships  exist  between  performance 
measures  and  elements  of  industry  structure  and  strategy  for  firms  in 
different   strategic  groups.   Thus,  careful  modelling  of  the  strategy- 
structure  relationship  should  highlight  the  important  strategic  factors 
(and  variables)  for  each  strategic  group  and  indicate  how  they  differ 
across  groups.   For  example,  in  one  of  the  Purdue  brewing  studies 
(Patton  (1976))  the  relationship  between  Debt  (strategic  element)  and 
ROE  (a  performance  measure),  was  examined  for  each  strategic  group.   For 
the  national  brewer  strategic  group  and  for  the  small  regional  brewer 
strategic  group  positive  relationships  were  found  (regression 
coefficients  of  0.15  and  0.33  respectively).   On  the  other  hand,  for  the 
large  regional  strategic  group  the  relationship  was  found  to  be 


-27- 

negative  (regression  coefficients  of  -0.61).   Clearly  the  relevance  of 
debt  and  the  influence  of  debt  varies  markedly  across  strategic 
groups.   Similar  patterns  can  be  found  for  other  key  strategic  dimen- 
sions in  those  and  other  studies.   Therefore,  the  strategic  importance 
of  certain  key  dimensions  can  more  clearly  be  assessed. 

Porter  (1980:   138-140)  also  argued  that  the  structure  of  strate- 
gic groups  has  implications  in  explaining  industry  rivalry,  and  hence, 
firm  performance.   Strategic  groups  characteristics,  such  as,  the 
number  of  strategic  groups,  the  extent  to  which  different  strategic 
groups  are  competing  for  the  same  customers,  and  the  strategic 
distance  among  strategic  groups  were  mentioned  by  Porter  as  important 
elements.   Hergert  (1983)  showed  empirically  that  the  characteristics 
of  strategic  group  structure  affect  the  market  performance  of  firms 
within  industries. 

In  summary,  the  strategic  groups  structure  within  an  industry  has 
an  impact  on  firms  performance.   Therefore,  when  either  existing  or 
potential  firms  are  trying  to  evaluate  their  future  performance  poten- 
tial, the  strategic  groups  structure  as  well  as  the  characteristics  of 
the  specific  group  should  be  considered. 
Understanding  Strategic  Group  Dynamics 

Understanding  dynamics  in  strategic  management  is  crucial  since 
the  formulation  of  competitive  strategy  is  an  evolutionary  process. 
Several  writers  have  investigated  dynamic  aspects  of  strategic  groups. 
Oster  (1982),  and  Fiegenbaum  and  Primeaux  (1983,  1985)  found  a  low 
level  of  movement  among  strategic  groups.   Huff,  Thomas,  and 
Fiegenbaum  (1985)  have  considered  the  role  of  grounded  theories  and 


-28- 

model  building  approaches  in  understanding  strategic  group  dynamics 
and  speculate  that  organizational  inertia  barriers  (MacMillan  and 
McCafferty  (1982),  Harrigan  (1980))  as  well  as  mobility  barriers  may 
hinder  shifts  between  groups  and  thus  explain  the  low  level  of  move- 
ment.  Further  research  on  this  topic  should  provide  important  guide- 
lines for  the  determination  of  competitive  strategy. 

The  Prediction  of  Benchmark  Strategic  Groups 

The  studies  of  Kumar,  Thomas,  and  Fiegenbaum  (1984a,  1984b)  have 
highlighted  another  aspect  of  strategic  group  dynamics.   Examining 
the  nature  of  the  future  strategic  group  equilibrium  as  the  industry 
evolves  can  provide  guidelines  (benchmarks)  for  strategic  planners 
in  examining  the  viability  of  alternative  competitive  strategies. 
Some  future  strategic  group  positions  may  appear  more  attractive  as  the 
firm  considers  the  match  between  its  skills  and  the  available  environ- 
mental opportunities. 

SUMMARY 
Today,  13  years  after  the  publication  of  Hunt's  (1972)  study, 
there  is  much  confusion  about  the  implementation  of  the  strategic 
group  concept  (McGee  and  Thomas  (1986)).   The  main  problem  is  that 
different  researchers  have  used  different  measures  to  describe  the 
firms'  strategy.   They  range  from  one  variable  (e.g.,  market  share)  to 
many  variables.   Most  of  the  studies  have  treated  the  problem  sta- 
tically, rather  than  dynamically.   According  to  Mintzberg  (1978:  934), 
strategy  is  "a  pattern  in  a  stream  of  decisions,"  that  is,  the 
behavior  over  time  of  a  firm's  actions,  an  aspect  not  considered  in 


-29- 

most  studies.   In  their  study  of  the  brewing  industry  Hatten  and 
Schendel  (1977:  110)  concluded  that  "attention  to  homogeneity  over 
time,  as  across  sections,  is  likely  to  be  worthwhile."   Indeed,  in  a 
later  study  Hatten  and  Hatten  (1985)  found  that  both  group  membership 
and  the  strategic  relationships  clearly  changed  over  time. 

Huff,  Thomas,  and  Fiegenbaum  (1985)  argued  for  more  research  into 
the  dynamics  of  strategic  groups.   Since  the  firm's  environment  and 
its  expectations  and  objectives  are  not  stable  over  time,  it  is  reaso- 
nable to  expect  that  the  structure  of  strategic  groups  may  also 
change  over  time. 

It  is  clearly  important  to  investigate  the  linkage  between 
strategic  groups  and  competitive  strategy  processes  so  as  to  develop  a 
clearer  theoretical  framework  for  the  determination  of  strategic 
groups.   One  key  issue  in  this  framework  is  the  appropriate  definition 
of  strategy. 

For  more  than  three  decades,  researchers  in  the  field  of  strategic 
management  have  discussed  this  question  of  definition.   Broadly 
defined,  a  firm's  strategy  matches  its  internal  resources  and  skills 
against  the  threats  and  opportunities  created  by  its  external  environ- 
ment (Hofer  and  Schendel  (1978:  12)).   Most  would  argue  that  a  firm's 
strategy  can  be  described  in  terms  of  three  major  dimensions: 

1)  The  level  of  strategy  (enterprise,  corporate,  business,  and 
functional ) . 

2)  The  component  of  strategic  decisions  (scope,  resource, 
deployment,  competitive  advantage,  and  synergism). 

3)  The  influence  of  time  on  strategic  decisions. 


-30- 

These  three  dimensions  capture  the  nature  of  the  strategic 
environment.   Figure  1  defines  the  dimensions  of  the  STRATEGIC  SPACE 
(SSP).   Thus,  a  firm's  strategic  decisions  in  each  level  of  the 


organization  and  for  each  time  period  can  be  depicted  in  terms  of  the 
SSP.  It  can  be  seen  immediately  that  strategic  groups  can  be  defined 
for  each  level  of  the  organization,  for  each  strategic  component,  and 
for  each  time  period  as  well  as  for  any  combination  of  the  three. 

Following  Porter's  (1981b)  suggestion  in  an  anti-trust  symposium, 
and  McGee  and  Thomas's  (1985)  paper,  in-depth  historical  analysis  of  an 
industry  can  supplement  strategic  group  analysis  by  enabling  managers 
and  extra-firm  policy  makers  to  make  sense  of  complex  industries. 
Further,  the  industry  study  of  strategic  groups  obtained  by  quantitative 
approaches  such  as  multivariate  analysis  should  be  validated  by  managers 
and  industry  analysts  as  they  try  to  understand  competition  and  close 
competitors  in  an  industry.   It  should  be  noted  that  little  follow-up 
with  industry  participants  has  been  reported  except  in  the  case  of  the 
Purdue  brewing  industry  studies  (Hatten  (1974)  and  others)  and  the  more 
recent  studies  of  Frazier  and  Howell  (1983),  Dess  and  Davis  (1984)  and 
Hawes  and  Crittenden  (1984).   This  richer  industry-study  approach  is 
also  consistent  with  studies  on  strategic  groups  by  Hunt  (1972)  on  the 
home  appliance  industry  and  by  Hatten  (1974)  and  Patton  (1976)  on  the 
brewing  industry. 

CONCLUSIONS 
Studying  strategic  groups  can  highlight  different  aspects  of 
competitive  strategy.   First,  identifying  the  strategic  dimensions 


-31- 

that  define  strategic  groups  is  a  key  issue  in  understanding  how 
competitors  formulate  their  strategies.   Second,  strategic  groups  help 
us  understand  which  firms  compete  strongly  with  each  other.   Third, 
strategic  groups  can  throw  light  upon  the  character  and  performance 
differences  associated  with  the  range  of  competitive  strategies 
adopted  in  the  industry.   Fourth,  the  strategic  groups  structure  can 
be  used  as  a  framework  for  modelling  competition  and  hence  in  explain- 
ing performance  differences  between  strategic  groups.   Fifth,  an 
understanding  of  the  dynamics  of  strategic  groups  is  useful  in 
explaining  changes  in  competitive  strategy  over  time.   Sixth,  the 
concept  of  benchmark  strategic  groups  (which  represent  long-run 
competitive  equilibruim  positions)  may  be  important  in  understanding 
future  strategic  group  positions. 


-32- 


Ref erences 


Andrews,  K. ,  The  Concept  of  Corporate  Strategy.   Horaewood,  111.: 
Dow-Jones,  1971. 

Andrews,  P.  W.  S.  ,  "Industrial  Analysis  in  Economics,"  In  Andrews  and 
Wilson  (eds.),  Oxford  Studies  in  Price  Mechanism,  1951. 

Ansoff,  H.  I.,  Corporate  Strategy,  New  York:   McGraw-Hill,  1965. 

Bain,  Joe  S. ,  Barriers  to  New  Competition.   Cambridge,  Mass.:   Harvard 
University  Press,  1956. 

Bain,  Joe  S.,  Industrial   Organization,  2d  ed .   New  York:   John  Wiley 
&  Sons,  1968. 

Baird,  I.  S. ,  and  Sudharshan,  D. ,  "Strategic  Groups:   A  Three  Mode 
Factor  Analysis  of  Some  Measures  of  Financial  Risk,"  WP  No.  931, 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign ,  Feb:   1983. 

Bass,  F.  M. ,  Cattin,  P.,  and  Wittink,  D.  R. ,  "Firm  Effects  and  Industry 
Effects  in  the  Analysis  of  Market  Structure  and  Profitability," 
Journal  of  Marketing  Research,  1978,  15,  3-10. 

Baumol,  L.  J.,  Business  Behavior,  Value  and  Growth,  rev.  ed . , 
Harcourt,  Brace,  1967. 

Bracker,  Jeffrey,  "The  Historical  Development  of  the  Strategic  Manage- 
ment Concept,"  Academy  of  Management  Review,  1980,  Vol.  5,  No.  2, 
219-224. 

Camerer,  C. ,  "Redirecting  Research  in  Business  Policy  and  Strategy," 
Strategic  Management  Journal,  6,  1985,  1-15. 

Comanor,  W.  S. ,  and  Wilson,  T.  A.,  "Advertising  Market  Structure  and 
Performance,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  Nov  1967, 
A23-440. 

Cannon,  J.  T.  ,  Business  Strategy  and  Policy.   New  York:   Harcourt, 
Brace  &  World  Inc.,  1968. 

Caves,  R.  ,  American  Industry:   Structure,  Conduct,  Performance,  4th 
edition.   Prentice-Hall  Inc.,  1977. 

Caves,  R.  E.  and  Porter,  M.  E. ,  "From  Entry  Barriers  to  Mobility 

Barriers,"  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  91,  May  1977,  241-261. 

Chaffee,  E.  E.  ,  "Three  Models  of  Strategy,"  Academy  of  Management 
Review,  10,  1985,  89-98. 


-33- 


Chandler,  A.  D. ,  Strategy  and  Structure.   Cambridge,  Mass.:   MIT 
Press,  1962. 

Collins,  Norman  R.  and  Preston,  Lee  E.,  Concentration  and  Price-Cost 
Margins  in  Manufacturing  Industries.   Berkeley:   University  of 
California  Press,  1968. 

Dess ,  G.  G.  and  Beard,  D.  W.  ,  "Dimensions  of  Organizational  Task 

Environments,"  Administrative  Science  Quarterly,  29  (1984)  52-73. 

Dess,  G.  G.  and  Davis,  P.  S.  ,  "Porter's  (1980)  Generic  Strategies  as 
Determinants  of  Strategic  Group  Membership  and  Organizational 
Performance,"  Academy  of  Management  Journal ,  Sept.  1984. 

Dirsmith,  W.  M.  and  Covaleski,  A.  M. ,  "Strategy,  External  Communication 
and  Environment  Context,"  Strategic  Management  Journal,  Vol.  4, 
137-151,  1983. 

Drucker,  P.  F. ,  Management:   Tasks,  Responsibilities,  Practices.   New 
York:   Harper  and  Row,  1974. 

Fiegenbaum,  A.  and  Primeaux,  Jr.,  W.  ,  "Strategic  Groups  and  Mobility 
Barriers:   The  Level  of  Struggle  in  an  Industry."   BEBR  Faculty 
Working  Paper  No.  984,  University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign, 
1983. 

Fiegenbaum,  A.,  and  Primeaux,  W.  J.,  "An  Empirical  Examination  of  the 
Dynamics  of  Strategic  Groups"  Cup  No.  1108,  University  of  Illinois 
at  Urbana-Champaign,  January,  1985. 

Fiegenbaum,  A.,  Sudharshan,  D. ,  and  Thomas,  H. ,  "The  Concept  of  Stable 
Strategic  Time  Periods  in  Strategic  Group  Research,"  Managerial 
and  Decision  Economics,  forthcoming,  1986. 

Fiol ,  C.  M. ,  "A  Search  for  Relevance  in  the  Study  of  Strategic  Groups," 
Paper  presented  at  the  National  Academy  of  Management  Meetings, 
August  1984. 

Frazier,  G.  L.  and  Howell,  R.  D. ,  "Business  Definition  and 
Performance,"  Journal  of  Marketing,  1983,  47,  59-67. 

Gale,  B.  T. ,  "Market  Share  and  the  Rate  of  Return,"  Review  of  Economics 
and  Statistics,  LIV ,  1972,  pp.  417-423. 

Galbraith,  J.  and  Nathanson,  D. ,  Strategy  Implementation:   The  Role  of 
Structure  and  Process.   St.  Paul:   West  Publishing  Company,  1978. 

Galbraith,  J.  and  Schendel ,  D.  E. ,  "An  Empirical  Analysis  of  Strategy 
Types,"  Strategy  Management  Journal,  4,2,  1983,  153-173. 


-34- 


Glueck,  William,  Business  Policy,  Strategy  Formulation  and  Management 
Action.   New  York:   McGraw-Hill,  1976. 

Gluck,  F. ,  Kaufmann,  S.  ,  and  Walleck,  A.  S. ,  "The  Four  Phases  of 

Strategic  Management"   Journal  of  Business  Strategy,  1982,  2(3), 
9-21. 

Gort,  M. ,  Diversification  and  Integration  in  American  Industry. 
Princeton:   Princeton  University  Press,  1962. 

Hall,  M. ,  and  Weiss,  L.  ,  "Firm  Size  and  Profitability,"  The  Review  of 
Economics  and  Statistics,  Vol  XLIV,  No.  3,  August  1967,  pp. 
319-331. 

Hatten,  K.  I.,  "Strategic  Models  in  the  Brewing  Industry." 

Unpublished  Doctoral  Dissertation,  Harvard  University,  1974. 

Hatten,  K.  J.,  and  Hatten,  M.  L. ,  "Some  Empirical  Insights  for 

Strategic  Marketers:   The  Case  of  Beer,"  In  H.  Thomas  and  Gardner, 
D.   M.  (eds.),  Strategic  Marketing  and  Management,  Chichester: 
John  Wiley,  1985. 

Hatten,  K.  I.  and  Schendel,  D.  £, ,  "Heterogeneity  Within  an  Industry: 
Firm  Conduct  in  the  U.S.  Brewing  Industry,  1952-1971,"  The  Journal 
of  Industrial  Economics,  1977,  26,  97-113. 

Hatten,  K.  I.,  Schendel,  D.  E. ,  and  Cooper,  A.,  "A  Strategic  Model  of 
the  U.S.  Brewing  Industry:   1952-1971,"  Academy  of  Management 
Journal,  1978,  21,  592-610. 

Harrigan,  K.  R.  ,  Strategies  for  Declining  Business,  New  York: 
Lexington  Books,  1980. 

Harrigan,  K.  R. ,  "An  Application  of  Clustering  for  Strategic  Group 
Analysis,"  Strategic  Management  Journal,  6,  1985,  55-73. 

Hawes,  M.  J.  and  Crittenden,  F.  W. ,  "A  Taxonomy  of  Competitive 

Retailing  Strategies,"  Strategic  Management  Journal,  5,  1984, 
275-287. 

Hayes,  A.,  Spence ,  M.  ,  and  Marks,  D. ,  Competitive  Structure  in 
Investment  Banking,  1983. 

Henderson,  B.  ,  Henderson  on  Corporate  Strategy,  Abbott  Books, 
Cambridge,  Mass,  1979. 

Hergert,  M.  ,  "The  Incidence  and  Implications  of  Strategic  Grouping  in 
U.S.  Manufacturing  Industries,"  Unpublished  Doctoral  Dissertation, 
Harvard  University,  1983. 


-35- 


Hofer,  C.  W.  ,  "Some  Preliminary  Research  on  Patterns  of  Strategic 
Behavior.*'   Proceedings  of  the  Business  Policy  and  Planning 
Division  of  the  Academy  of  Management,  Paper  7/5,  Boston,  August 
1973. 

Hofer,  C.  W.  and  Schendel,  D. ,  Strategy  Formulation:   Analytical 
Concepts .   St.  Paul:   West  Publishing  Company,  1978. 

Hunt,  M.  S. ,  "Competition  in  the  Major  Home  Appliance  Industry,  1960- 
1970,"  Unpublished  Ph.D.  Dissertation,  Harvard  University,  1972. 

Huff,  A.  S. ,  Thomas,  H. ,  and  Fiegenbaum,  A.,  "Modeling  Strategic 
Moves:   Toward  Understanding  Strategic  Group  Dynamics,"  WP, 
University  of  Illinois,  1985. 

Karnani,  A.,  and  Wernerfelt,  B.  ,  "Multiple  Point  Competition," 
Strategic  Management  Journal,  1985,  6,  87-96. 

Khandwalla,  P.  N. ,  "Environment  and  Its  Impact  on  the  Organization," 
International  Studies  of  Management  and  Organization,  2,  1972, 
297-313. 

Kumar,  K.  R. ,  Thomas,  H.  and  Fiegenbaum,  A.,  "Benchmark  Strategic 
Grouping  for  Formulating  Future  Competitive  Strategy,"  WP  1087, 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign,  November,  1984a. 

Kumar,  K.  R. ,  Thomas,  H.  and  Fiegenbaum,  A.,  "Strategic  Groups  and 
Competitive  Equilibrium:   A  Game  Theoretic  Approach"  WP  1083, 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign,  October  1984b. 

Lippman,  S.  A.,  and  Rumelt,  R.  P.,  "Efficiency  Differentials  Under 
Competition:   A  Stochastic  Approach  to  Industrial  Organization," 
UCLA,  1981. 

MacMillan,  I.  C. ,  and  McCafferty,  M.  L. ,  "Strategies  For  Low  Entry 
Barrier  Markets  such  as  Service  Industries"   Journal  of  Business 
Strategy,  1982 

McGee,  J.,  "Strategic  Groups:   Review  and  Prospects."   In  H.  Thomas  and 
Gardner,  D.  M.  (Eds.),  Strategic  Marketing  and  Management. 
Chichester:   John  Wiley,  1985. 

McGee,  J.,  and  Thomas,  H. ,  "Making  Sense  of  Complex  Industries,"  WP, 
University  of  Illinois  at  Urbana-Champaign,  1985. 

McGee,  J.,  and  Thomas,  H.  ,  "Strategic  Groups:   Theory,  Research  and 
Taxonomy,"  forthcoming  in  Strategic  Management  Journal,  1986. 


-36- 


Miller,  Danny,  "The  Role  of  Multivariate  'Q-Techniques '  in  the  Study 
of  Organizations,"  Academy  of  Management  Review,  July  1978, 
515-531. 

Miller,  D.  and  Friesen,  P.  H. ,  "Archetypes  of  Organizational 

Transition,"  Administrative  Science  Quarterly,  25,  1980,  208-299. 

Miller,  D.  and  Friesen,  P.  H. ,  "Strategy-making  and  Environment:   The 
Third  Link,"  Strategic  Management  Journal,  Vol.  4,  221-235,  1983. 

Mintzberg,  H. ,  "Patterns  in  Strategy  Formation,"  Management  Science, 
1978,  24,  934-948. 

Morris,  R. ,  The  Ecomomic  Theory  of  Managerial  Capitalism.   Macmillian, 
1964. 

Newman,  H.  H. ,  "Strategic  Groups  and  the  Structure  Performance 
Relationships:   A  Study  with  Respect  to  the  Chemical  Process 
Industries,"  Unpublished  Ph.D.  Dissertation,  Harvard  University, 
1973. 

Newman,  H.  H. ,  "Strategic  Groups  and  the  Structure  Performance 

Relationship,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  1978,  60,  376-383. 

Oster,  S. ,  "Intraindustry  Structure  and  the  Ease  of  Strategic  Change," 
Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  1982,  64,  376-383. 

Paine,  F.  and  Naumes,  W. ,  Strategy  and  Policy  Formulation:   An 
Integrative  Approach.   Philadelphia:   Saunders,  1974. 

Patton,  G.  R. ,  "A  Simultaneous  Equation  Model  of  Corporate  Strategy: 
The  Case  of  the  U.S.  Brewing  Industry,"  Unpublished  Ph.D.  Disser- 
tation, Purdue  University,  1976. 

Pettigrew,  A.,  "Strategy  Formulation  as  a  Political  Process," 

International  Studies  of  Management  and  Organization,  vol.  7,  no. 
2  (Summer  1977),  pp.  78-87. 

Pitts,  R.  A.  and  Hopkins,  D.  H. ,  "Firm  Diversity:   Conceptualization 
and  Measurement"   Academy  of  Management  Review,  1982,  7,  620-629. 

Pitts,  Robert  A.,  "Strategies  and  Structures  for  Diversification," 
Academy  of  Management  Journal,  1977,  Vol.  20,  No.  2,  197-208. 

Porter,  M.  E. ,  "The  Structure  Within  Industries  and  Companies' 
Performance,"  Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics,  61,  1979, 
214-219. 

Porter,  M.  E. ,  Competitive  Strategy.   New  York:   The  Free  Press,  1980. 


-37- 


Porter,  M.  E. ,  "The  Contribution  of  Industrial  Organization  to 

Strategic  Management,"  Academy  of  Management  Review,  1981,  Vol.  6, 
No.  4,  609-620. 

Porter,  M.  E.  ,  Competitive  Advantage.   New  York:   The  Free  Press,  1985. 

Primeaux,  W.  J.,  "The  Interdependence  of  the  Life  Cycle  and  Strategic 
Group  Concepts:   Theory  and  Evidence."   Working  paper  No.  961, 
University  of  Illinois-Urbana,  College  of  Commerce  and  Business 
Administration,  1983. 

Primeaux,  W.  J.,  "A  Method  for  Determining  Strategic  Groups  and  Life 
Cycle  Stages  of  an  Industry."   In  H.  Thomas  and  Gardner,  D.  M. 
(eds.),  Strategic  Marketing  and  Management.   Chichester:   John 
Wiley,  1985. 

Quinn,  J.  B. ,  Strategies  for  Change.   Homewood ,  111.:   Richard  D.  Irwin, 
Inc.,  1980. 

Ramsler,  M. ,  "Strategic  Groups  and  Foreign  Market  Entry  in  Global 
Banking  Competition,"  Unpublished  Ph.D.  Dissertation,  Harvard 
University,  August  1982. 

Rumelt,  R.  P.,  Strategy,  Structure  and  Economic  Performance.   Boston: 
Harvard  Business  School  Division  of  Research,  1974. 

Rumelt,  R.  P.,  "Toward  a  Strategic  Theory  of  the  Firm,"  paper  prepared 
for  a  conference  on  Non-traditional  Approaches  to  Policy  Research, 
Graduate  School  of  Business,  University  of  Southern  California, 
1981. 

Ryans ,  B.  A.  and  Wittink,  D.  R. ,  "Security  Returns  as  a  Basis  for 

Estimating  the  Competitive  Structure  in  an  Industry."   In  Thomas, 
H.  and  Gardner,  D.  M.  (Eds.),  Strategy  Marketing  and  Management. 
Chichester:   John  Wiley,  1985. 

Schendel,  D.  and  Hofer,  C.  W. ,  Strategic  Management:   A  New  View  of 
Business  Policy  and  Planning.   Boston:   Little  Brown,  1979. 

Schendel,  D.  E. ,  and  Patton,  R.  G. ,  "A  Simultaneous  Equation  Model  of 
Corporate  Strategy,"  Management  Science,  24,  1978,  1611-1621. 

Scherer,  F.  M.  ,  Industrial  Market  Structure  and  Economic  Performance, 
2nd  ed.,  Chicago:   Rand  McNally  College  Publishing  Company,  1980. 

Shepherd,  G.  W. ,  "The  Elements  of  Market  Structure,"  The  Review  of 
Economics  and  Statistics,  vol.  LIV,  No.  1,  February  1972,  pp. 
25-37. 


-38- 


Shepherd,  G.  W. ,  The  Economics  of  Industrial  Organization.   Prentice- 
Hall,  Inc.,  1979. 

Shirley,  C.  Robert,  "Limiting  the  Scope  of  Strategy:   A  Decision-Based 
Approach,"  Academy  of  Management  Review,  1982,  Vol.  7,  No.  2, 
262-268. 

Snow,  C.  C.  and  Hambrick,  D.  C. ,  "Measuring  Organizational  Strategies: 
Some  Theoretical  and  Methodological  Problems,"  Academy  of 
Management  Review,  1980,  5,  527-538. 

Steiner,  G.  A.  and  Miner,  J.  B. ,  Management  Policy  and  Strategy: 
Text,  Readings  and  Cases.   New  York.:   Macmillan,  1977. 

Stigler,  G.  J.,  "A  Theory  of  Oligopoly,"  Journal  of  Political  Economy, 
Jan,  1964,  44-61. 

Vernon,  John  M.  ,  Market  Structure  and  Industrial  Performance:   A 

Review  of  Statistical  Findings.   Boston:   Allyn  and  Bacon,  Inc., 
1972. 

Van  Cauvenbergh,  A.,  and  Cool,  K. ,  "Strategic  Management  in  a  New 
Framework,"  Strategic  Management  Journal,  3,  1982,  245-265. 

Williamson,  J.  D. ,  "Profit,  Growth  and  Sales  Maximization,"  Economica , 
33,  Feb. ,  1966,  1-16. 

Williamson,  0.  E. ,  "Managerial  Discretion  and  Business  Behavior," 
American  Economic  Review,  53,  December  1963,  1032-57. 


D/372 


Figure  1 


TIME 


i<?r 


Resource   Competitive 
\C\-yt  s^  Scope Deployment    Advantage     Synergism 


Enterprise 
Corporate 
Business 
Functional 


LEVEL 


Figure  1:   The  Strategic  Space  (SSP) 


Figure  2 


Figure  2:   Risk/Return  Groups 
Risk   ...  " 


4 


3h 


Return  (ROE) 


Cf 


s*e  cjf  ee 


A     3      A     «w   3 

-1       Q.      □      v_      n. 


55 

od  a. 


* 
a.  -• 


ss 

a 


3  i  3    N 

C  I  r.    -. 

ft  »-  3"  — 

r»  3  (1    1 


*-  CT  —  *- 

3  1  3  w 

a.  a 

c  c  r>  *» 


D    -D    O 

£^8 


Z"  1 


3-  •» 
ft    PI 

i  a 
»    • 

e 


en   » 

frB 

ft   a. 

n   *- 

c  *• 

O    -1 

r»     3     3 

00    B 

•—   »    c 

A    •* 

n 

3     3     •"■• 

•   a 

ft   ■ 

oq   n   m 

"i 

^   — 

•*  o 

n   a 

3-  H 

•    ft    -■ 

ft    3 

►-  ft 

r»     *-   C 

•O    n 

n 

"1            n 

■1 

ft 

B    »    *- 

A    < 

ft    3 

r»     3     3 

a    • 

n  a. 

ft    O.M 

A  "I 

—.  -b,  ^  r- 

r»  O  w  A 

3*  •-  O  ft 

a  »-  m  a. 


■    »   » 

»    -    ~ 


3-  rt  -o     ft 

A    A  n     3" 

»-0Q  O     A 

-    -  c    y 

o  c    «- 

•  no 

rt  0Q  r»     ft 

n    »n  •    •— 

ft   O  • 
r»    C 

n  *j  ft 

OQ   •  5 

■*  o. 
n   • 

o  ft 

no  »- 

»-  o  •- 


cr 

n 

•>*>    — 

ft 

r 

O    ** 

a 

•D 

T3 

P 

T3 

p 

•-ft. 

» 

o 

o  c 

oq 

-3 

•*»  3 

o> 

n 

i 

E 

ft 

c 

c 

« 

D 

o    •— 

»i 

n 

o 

3 

3 

ft 

OQ 

Q.  •— 

o 

"O     A 

a. 

C 

C 

B 

A 

o 

a  oq 

o 

c 

ft 

O 

"0    ft* 

c 

• 

rt     n 

a 

r> 

ft 

ft 

B 

-i     ft 

ft 

A 

ft 

o 

o 

D 

a 

O     3 

0     « 

n 

3 

3 

n 

a.  ft 

c 

—    fl 

■ 

a 

c 

a 

c 

il 

O 

ft 

c 

H 

A     & 

1 

■*1 

3 

o  -o 

ft 

*o 

C 

* 

ft 

A 

I 

rt 

£ 

a 

ft 

rt    n 

n 

Q  *Q 

r» 

3 

•^ 

*1 

B 

•    0 

o 

•i 

ft 

& 

*7J 

0. 

o 

ft 

■o   o 

n 

ft 

c 

=r 

E 

«-t   a. 

o 

0 

* 

■^ 

o 

A 

o 

o   c 

ft 

a 

D 

ft 

B 

■ 

a.  o 

n 

• 

k 

• 

■— 

H 

n 

c   a 

m 

— 

■— 

O     ft     0    f 


8  «  2 

3-    <     ft    3 

C     ft     3     6     ft     1 

r.     g    >• 

n 

ft     ft     ft 

<r  •* 

i 

-     -      ■-    « 

r-        1        -       3        -      - 

~     ~.    1 

i 

ft     ft    O 

>•   B    3-        ft   n 

3     11 

< 

~  00     ^    B 

■W     ft     ft     G.    3     •* 

a    ■    * 

# 

31   ft            ft 

»-&.••»         ^ 

C      =r  3 

ft            X 

ft            ft     ••  *^  ft 

ft     m   rt 

• 

~  8     C     3 

r>    ^3 

» 

06     3"    ft     ft     ^  •— 

n     ft    ft 

o   i    c   a. 

•-   »    T)    C 

*      -      C      1       ' 

ft    k*  n 

^           ft    ft 

>-          a    3    •*»  r> 

ft     3    ft 

O  ■«            r. 

.     _   _    o    •      3- 

C    i     C    " 

.      •_   ft     ft           ft 

a  ft 

ft    O     ft    •• 

-     ft 

—  •» 

-.    —    -    n 

p           >-    M  ft 

•»  •> 

ft    —    t    • 

«    r.    r    3   ft 

••  o 

y      "8 

3    ft     r.           ft 

6  -<    3- 

<             ft            • 

ft 

ft    ft     0    " 

I 

3     CT     3     3" 

a.  —        n 

c    9 


r»  ft  rt  3  -- 

ft  "  ft  ft 

OQ  ft  OQ  ^  •— 

•»  3  »-  »-l  ft 

O  r.  o  o  **■ 


C  "*     CT   3* 

•o     CX   ft     •*  •- 
•      .-    ct     —  -o 


ft  »-  ft 
3  ■  3 
r»  C 


ft    0Q     "ft  ft 

3-    ft 

>-    ft      r.  ft 

3     1     ft  0 

Q.           0Q  1 

C     «    **  ft 
ft     3*    O 

r*     ft  3 

n          OQ  O 

^<    ^    i  0 

-     i    o  o 

O     C  OQ 

«-»  -O  ft 

-      « 

r.   .  O 

C 

c    «  • 

•«    3" 
r»     ft 


^ft" 


ft-2.? 

O  ft 

ft     rt    5 


O.  (V) 

•<  r» 

3  ft 

ft  r* 

t? 


b    X  ^»» 

K. -«       ^  6.  — 

?■         u  b  a. 
w  p, 

pi  •  • 

f  ">  ?  2 


oo 
■8  A 
1    3 

>•  tr 
If 


■     rt      D 


"I 


if 


O.  1 

•>  A 

■O    ■ 
p-  O 

o  c 


A    A 

►»  o 
o  c 


I!  S 


n         ■ 

—  •  -a 


• 


c  ►» 


S.-S 

C    «"■ 

•  1 

r>   O 


rt  3  r» 
pi  &  B 
►»         I* 


a         B 

!  p 


E-? 


►—  •    O     rt 


<»-C<-*rtrtrt 

.-  •  -  re  3  V  C  =r 
o.  n  i-  *  a  n  rt  rt 
e    bk   -y   r*   ►*■   "    rt 

5.2  -  S^S  3E 

3-    3    O.    •»    i»    «"» 

oob"CB3*o 
S    S.   "  B     "    A    3" 


p-   A    "3    < 


p.    ■    -O 
A    B    1 


O.  in 
<    " 

3     » 
•    n 

E." 


n    »»  o    • 


o    S         o    n   er 

03<-»3p-B3*A 
B     O.    A     »"  3  •      I 

(t     -    ->  I     O      I 

111  ~> 


no  *^  I 

b    3   i»    a    w  o.  >  ' 

n    o    «    d    t    c  r»     ' 

3     i-l  OQ     rt    n   n  "**■ 

O    vc    3     -          «  </>' 


c  «• 
1  3 
A  00 


-     A 
A     3 


•o  C 

—  •O 

3  • 
• 

3  » 

n  o 

p-  n 

*  o 


p-  A 

><  00 

pi 

■o  o 

n    c 
P-TO 


A    O  n    A 
•<■»■» 

r.     P-  T      O. 

O  r.    A 

«J  <  1 

O  A  B 

M  **  3*00 


■    ■  _ 

S   rt  n    r  '   I 

r>   A  B    O  •    — 

se  •»  ►»  —  =■ 

n  o  >-  o 

•  "  r 

«  M  <  A 

•11  •  < 

BO  p»  • 

<■>    C  ■"" 

A  ^  O 

R    ■  *»  O 


—    —  C 


•D  « 

r*  p- 

3  B 

00  B 

B 

r-  O. 


on 

<     O 

p| 

n   n 

0 

US: 

C 

T> 

3     3 

B 

r»  0Q 

So" 

S 

a.  r* 

B     ft    <X     O 
A    rt     1    *•• 

i  c 

n   i 

3    ft     O    "* 

o 

2 

3  -• 

n«     C     <* 

•    •— 

re   ^   »» 

•     rt 

8 

tm    ■* 

fta  ft     »    n 

< 

«»00 

»-               rt 

r>    A 

a. 

—  O     ft     3 

rt, 

*%    rt 

r»      »--.     -i      « 

a. 

rt 

•    O 

0Q 

o   n         » 

ft     i 

X     3"     O    rt 

■ 

o   o 

n   rt    a    *-. 

11 

n   c 
o  -o 

B-                             ft 

r%   < 

n    ft 

.      3     **  rt 

A 

a 

<     — .00 

oc   e 

*-  n 

rt     -*  "- 

n    <» 

3     ft 

• 

O     3 

00     3 

rt     n 

:  ? 


It    g    A    o    e    •   a 

—    O    ■"» 
p*   C    "^ 

B     A 

t—   A 
A     A      3     B              3    A 

A    "O    A 

pi    •  n 

A            A 

n    B    t- 
A    A    A 
•0     3    < 

3     B     <     0   OX     O     ■"• 

3     |    3 

p-    «    A 

►-  a    a    A    i    b«  5 

n         p- 

►-   —    B     3    O     A     O 

00    E    o 

IB   3     H     n     C             "" 

B     O*    B 

nOQ     B»    A   "O     B    A 
K    OO      B     t      O-    B 

n    A    rt 
ty     I    1 

B     B    B 

O     3 

C    00    p. 

B    1            r»    A 

•*    3*  r* 

•O           •* 

"  °  *■  B  ^  C  JT 

A    p»  A 

•           *1 

B     C     -  00     A      3-3 

00  -o    ~  a          a    a. 

BUB 

B 

a       a       r  _  £ 

C      '     O     3     ~  • 

:  f" 

cr 


k  ■« 

3    »- 
O.  ft 


Ff 


c?e 


CD  * 


f 


.6 


vc  a. 


i   n 

zz 

«•  o 
—  o 

fit 


ft     !• 
n   o 

•-  3 


S  JT 


*  • 
o2 


a.  i 

ft  ft 
"O  ■ 
►-  O 


oca 

■    n    r> 


li  1 


•  an 

ft  • 


S.P 


*-    A   ^ 
r.    O 


BA    so  a  «  »    O  ■**■-»!  "O  ^ 

•    is*  Cnsn  3    3"  1   » 

3     ~  ■    O  ac  a    a    —  O   -o 

r»    »    •*  r*    0  OQ  C             —  a.  A 

•     -    •»  -i     -  ,i  •     cr  n  Cn 

*—  H  *»  ft  ►—  "o  r»     *n    p  o 

—    •  A  A    A  *l    A    to  rr 

•    ft*  •    •*>  n   n  *<C  • 

y»-                      D  l  m             ►*  *-. 

I    ft*                               I  C                  DO 

s  i 


T3    cr  oq  n  •  tj    •»  ^   kj 

h    i  A  3*  c  H    3  3*  K> 

O      0>  D  •  T3  O      fcV  A 

a.  o  a  **  a  o.  ■-•. 

c   a.  n  d  n  c    »  -o   — 

O  •*  •  d  ft    *-  to    n 

nOQ  O  to  rt»->-B 

AM  a*,  i-,  »      ~  D      • 

O  O  |T  A  n 

o  1  A  EL  •    •* 


'  ft     3*  A 

»  a  ■ 


o  a  *» 


E-o 


ZB 

O"  rr 
»—  a 


i  ►»  a 
■  a  • 
«->  «o 


*-          »»  r»  ft  a  00 

O    1  1  13 

<           3    a  ft  n  < 

ft            B    <-?  3  a  a 

*1                    ft  r*  ■  r| 

—                 OQ  ft  Nh 

*           ><  p  3  m 

or  a  n  o" 

•-                O.  1  — 

a              ►•  *•  a.  n 

a  B  «  -. 

a  r»  n* 

9  »»  I 

I  3 


It  s 


o  o 

o.  g 
a  -o 


1— 

»  n 

.tola)   K> 

»— 

c 

3  c 

3 

cl  a 

O 

t~> 

ft  o 
c    B 

to 

a> 

?tc 

:£ 

o 

at   n 

1 

•t 

a»  »    o 

*-  < 

3 

r»   »-i 

A 

n 

n 

**  a    -^. 

n  n 

Of 

O 

3 

ft 

3  r»    m 

•  n 

B  OQ 

3 

n    "^j» 

r* 

ft     H 

to 

a>    ®  — 

••  o 

CD 

«    a  <* 

« 

m    C 

fi» 

O 

*—m 

■o 

» 

§  . 

3 

a 

OQ 

«  o 

a   x 

i  •- 

BS 

o   »• 

c    — 

^-  ►* 

■o   » 

►-  o 

a  n 

3 

• 

or  a 

•■»  o 

n    «» 

o  « 

a  • 

n 

C 

•m, 

a  t 

a 

i   a 

a  o 

M 

n  •• 

«    — 

3- 

1    O 

a 

O    3 

-    r» 

c  a 

S    1 

■o   ►- 

c  a 

• 

C    r. 

a 

a  a 

a 

EE  2.; 


w  n  >•  > 

C      O     3    tfc 

5  2? 

It     3  *U 

O"    3     ►*  « 

«    •*  n 

*-*.»»  » 

B    •  n  n 

-l    «^*  c 

►»  a  •*  A 

1      A     • 

i     B 

a   i   a   a 

*—   n 

B      *     -* 

a   <   n  a 

►-    it 

m          •» 

—   »    o    - 

3 

S 

<     n    n    < 

O     r» 

•  »  a  a 

O     *- 

• 

< 

•    to 

o.  a 

a 

f»    " 

5 

r.  r.    H 

n  ft   a 

•»  ~ot 

f>  o   — 


oo  oo  at 
o    o    *■. 


n  o 

o 

«-  - 


o    PS 


sT  <  •"» 

»>>■)•« 

►-  A 

•-  a  i 

«  •—  A 

<  M  O 

ST  * 

»  i  ■ 

•  - 

»*  B  *1 

•-  r»  A 

A  rt 

•1  a-  A 

•  A  <X 

•  <  ►* 


**  «  o  ■  tn 

A  3  <  O  « 

n  A  A  •  n 

A  <1  1  r»  to 

0  A  n 

ft  «  a-  A 

A  to  *-  —  OQ 

•  "  B  w  - 

A  A  A  ft 


a  n  a  n 

i  t  t  i  I 

a  3  -  E  a 

«  rt  r*  **  ^ 

ft  a  ■»  o  ft 

a>  o  n 

•-  a  s  a  a 


?f 


B  D  S 


~  tx. 

•«J 

» 

TJ 

< 

•o 

a->    rt 

•m 

OQ 

n  3" 

T3    H 

O    i 

o 

1 

to 

A 

A      A 

A 

ft  O 

A     3 

n    o 

•^ 

•i 

c 

1    OQ 

n 

3 

"B 

1     A 

E4 

B 

o 

A      a* 

B 

A 

3*0 

• 

• 

to 

O 

3     ft 

A 

O 

AOQ 

O     A 

D     A 

A 

r*j 

n 

c 

1  A 

»*    r» 

ft 

» 

K 

—  Ot 

to 

3 

E  E 

■  Z 

3 

■ 

o- 

0 

"<       *! 

D 

rt  A 

3 

3 

O 

30 

3     ft 

•o    < 

C 

•1 

ft 

A      C 

Da 

3 

»  C 

ft     r» 

n    A 

to 

A 

3    ^ 

Ok 

3  A 

A     C 

O 

D 

Ck.     A 

c 

—  a. 

A 

»< 

• 

-O     A 

A 

Ot 

?  if 

A 

O  3 

to      1 

1 

| 

3 

•1 

->  O. 

•1     ft 

A     •"•> 

A 

ft 

3 

PI 

<     3" 

A 

c 

to    O 

a       A 

1 

D 

OQ 

C 

to 

A    to 

< 

3 

A 

A 

ST. 

a-  a. 

A 

n 

!X 

i 

&    to 

r»  *1 

oc   c 

3 

A 

o 

•1 

A 

A  — 

B   « 

n 

*1 

c 

C 

c 

3 

tm   a 

n 

n  a 

O  A 

r^ 

HECKMAN 

BINDERY  INC 

JUN95 

_     ,  N  MANCHESTER