Skip to main content

Full text of "A history of English law"

See other formats


A  HISTORY  OF  ENGLISH  LAW 


A  HISTORY  OF  ENGLISH  LAW 

IN  NINE  VOLUMES 
For  List  of  Volumes  and  Scheme  of  the  History,  see  p.  vii 


A    HISTORY 
OF    ENGLISH    LAW 


|i<  Wl1' Sf  HOLDSWORTH,  K.C.,  D.G.L. 

VINERIAN    PROFESSOR    OF    ENGLISH    LAW    IS    THE    UNIVERSITY    OF    OXFORD;      FELLOW    OF    ALL    SOULS 

COLLEGE,   OXFORD;     LATE   FELLOW  OF  ST.   JOHN*S   COLLEGE,   OXFORD;    FOREIGN'  ASSOCIATE 

OF  THE   ROYAL   BELGIAN   ACADEEY  ;     FELLOW  OF    THE   BRITISH    ACADEBY 


VOLUME  VIII 


To  say  truth,  although  it  is  not  necessary  for  counsel  to  know  what 
the  history  of  a  point  is,  but  to  know  how  it  now  stands  resolved,  yet  it  is  a 
•wonderful  accomplishment,  and,  without  it,  a  lawyer  cannot  be  accounted 
learned  in  the  law.  Roger  North 


METHUEN  &  GO.   LTD. 

36     ESSEX     STREET     W.C. 

LONDON 


K 

v.  a 


/}>.*•/  Published  in  1925 


PRINTED    IN    GREAT    BRITAIN 


TO 

The  Right  Honourable  FREDERICK  EDWIN 
EARL  OF  BIRKENHEAD 

SOMETIME    LORD    HIGH    CHANCELLOR    OF    GREAT    BRITAIN* 
THIS    WORK 


BY    HIS    LORDSHIP  S    PERMISSION 


RESPECTFULLY    DEDICATED 


PLAN  OF  THE    HISTORY 

(Vol.  I.)  BOOK  I. — The  Judicial  System  :  Introduction.  Chap.  I.  Origins. 
Chap.  II.  The  Decline  of  the  Old  Local  Courts  and  the  Rise  of  the  New  County 
Courts.  Chap.  III.  The  System  of  Common  Law  Jurisdiction.  Chap.  IV.  The  House 
of  Lords.  Chap.  V.  The  Chancery.  Chap.  VI.  The  Council.  Chap.  VII.  Courts 
of  a  Special  Jurisdiction.     Chap.  VIII.  The  Reconstruction  of  the  Judicial  System. 

(Vol.  II.)  BOOK  II.  (^49-1066) — Anglo-Saxon  Antiquities:  Introduction. 
Part  I.  Sources  and  General  Development.  Part  II.  The  Rules  of  Law :  §  1  The 
Ranks  of  the  People ;  §  2  Criminal  Law ;  §  3  The  Law  of  Property ;  §  4  Family  Law ; 
§5  Self-help  ;  §  6  Procedure. 

BOOK  III.  (1066-1485) — The  Medieval  Common  Law:  Introduction.  Part 
I.  Sources  and  General  Development :  Chap.  I.  The  Intellectual,  Political,  and 
Legal  Ideas  of  the  Middle  Ages.  Chap.  II.  The  Norman  Conquest  to  Magna  Carta. 
Chap.  III.  The  Reign  of  Henry  III.  Chap.  IV.  The  Reign  of  Edward  I.  Chap.  V. 
The  Fourteenth  and  Fifteenth  Centuries.  (Vol.  III.)  Part  II.  The  Rules  of  Law: 
Chap.  I.  The  Land  Law  :  §  1  The  Real  Actions ;  §  2  Free  Tenure,  Unfree  Tenure, 
and  Chattels  Real ;  §  3  The  Free  Tenures  and  Their  Incidents ;  §  4  The  Power  of 
Alienation;  §  5  Seisin:  §  6  Estates;  §  7  Incorporeal  Things;  §  8  Inheritance;  §  9 
Curtsey  and  Dower  ;  §  10  Unfree  Tenure ;  §  11  The  Term  of  Years ;  §  12  The  Modes 
and  Forms  of  Conveyance;  §  13  Special  Customs.  Chap.  II.  Crime  and  Tort: 
§  1  Self-help ;  §  2  Treason  ;  §  3  Benefit  of  Clergy,  and  Sanctuary  and  Abjuration ; 
§  4  Principal  and  Accessory ;  §  5  Offences  Against  the  Person  ;  §  6  Possession  and 
Ownership  of  Chattels ;  §  7  Wrongs  to  Property ;  §  8  The  Principles  of  Liability ; 
§  9  Lines  of  Future  Development.  Chap.  III.  Contract  and  Quasi-Contract.  Chap. 
IV.  Status:  §  1  The  King;  §2  The  Incorporate  Person;  §3  The  Villeins;  §  4  The 
Infant;  §  5  The  Married  Woman.  Chap.  V.  Succession  to  Chattels:  §  1  The  Last 
Will ;  §  2  Restrictions  on  Testation  and  Intestate  Succession ;  §  3  The  Representa- 
tion of  the  Deceased.  Chap.  VI.  Procedure  and  Pleading  :  §  1  The  Criminal  Law; 
§  2  The  Civil  Law. 

(Vol.  IV.)  BOOK  IV.  (1485-1700) — The  Common  Law  and  Its  Rivals:  Intro- 
duction. Part  I.  Sources  and  General  Development:  Chap.  I.  The  Sixteenth 
Century  at  Home  and  Abroad.  Chap.  II.  English  Law  in  the  Sixteenth  and  Early 
Seventeenth  Centuries :  The  Enacted  Law.  (Vol.  V.)  Chap.  III.  English  Law  in 
the  Sixteenth  and  Early  Seventeenth  Centuries  :  Developments  Outside  the  Sphere 
of  the  Common  Law — International,  Maritime,  and  Commercial  Law.  Chap.  IV. 
English  Law  in  the  Sixteenth  and  Early  Seventeenth  Centuries :  Developments  Out- 
side the  Sphere  of  the  Common  Law — Law  Administered  by  the  Star  Chamber  and 
the  Chancery.  Chap.  V.  English  Law  in  the  Sixteenth  and  Early  Seventeenth 
Centuries:  The  Development  of  the  Common  Law.  (Vol.  VI.)  Chap.  VI.  The 
Public  Law  of  the  Seventeenth  Century.  Chap.  VII.  The  Latter  Half  of  the  Seven- 
teenth Century :  The  Enacted  Law.  Chap.  VIII.  The  Latter  Half  of  the  Seven- 
teenth Century :  The  Professional  Development  of  the  Law. 

(Vol.  VII.)  Partll.  The  Rules  of  Law.  Chap.  I.  The  Land  Law  :§  1  The  Action 
of  Ejectment;  §  2  Seisin  Possession  and  Ownership;  §  3  Contingent  Remainders; 
§  4  Executory  Interests ;  §  5  Powers  of  Appointment;  §  6  The  Rules  Against  Per- 
petuities ;  §  7  Landlord  and  Tenant ;  §  8  Copyholds ;  §  9  Incorporeal  Things ;  §  10 
Conveyancing;  §  n  The  Interpretation  of  Conveyances.  Chap.  II.  Chattels 
Personal :  §  1  The  Action  of  Trover  and  Conversion ;  §  2  The  Ownership  and 
Possession  of  Chattels;  §3  Choses  in  Action.  (Vol.  VIII.)  Chap.  III.  Contract 
and  Quasi-Contract:  §  1  The  Doctrine  of  Consideration;  §  2  The  Invalidity,  the 
Enforcement,  and  the  Discharge  of  Contract ;  §  3  Quasi-Contract.  Chap.  IV.  The 
Law  Merchant.  I. — Commercial  Law  :  §  1  Usury  and  the  Usury  Laws ;  §  2 
Negotiable  Instruments  ;  §  3  Banking ;  §  4  Commercial  Societies  ;  §  5  Agency ;  §  6 
Bankruptcy.  II. — Maritime  Law.  III. — Insurance.  Chap.  V.  Crime  and  Tort. 
Lines  of  Development.  §  1  Constructive  Treason  and  Other  Cognate  Offences ;  §  2 
Defamation;  §3  Conspiracy,  Malicious  Prosecution,  and  Maintenance;  §4  Legal 
Doctrines  Resulting  from  Laws  Against  Religious  Nonconformity;  §  5  Lines  of 
Future  Development ;  §  6  The  Principles  of  Liability.  (Vol.  IX.)  Chap.  VI. 
Status :  §  1  The  King  and  Remedies  Against  the  Crown  ;  §  2  The  Incorporate 
Person ;  §  3  British  Subjects!  and  Aliens.  Chap.  VII.  Evidence,  Procedure,  and 
Pleading :  §  1  Evidence ;  §  2  Common  Law  Procedure ;  §  3  Equity  Procedure. 


CONTENTS 

PAGB 

Plan  of  the  History yii 

List  of  Cases xxiji 

List  of  Statutes nodi 

BOOK  IV  {continued) 

THE  COMMON  LAW  AND  ITS  RIVALS 

PART  II  (continued) 

THE  RULES  OF  LAW 

CHAPTER  III 

Contract  and  Quasi- Contract 

Agreement  and  Contract i 

The  problem  of  distinguishing  between  pact  and  contract   ....  1-2 

Mainly  solved  by  the  doctrine  of  consideration 2 

Other  topics  dealt  with  in  this  chapter 2 

§  1.  The  Doctrine  of  Consideration 2-48 

The  term  consideration 3-8 

The  need  for  a  test  to  distinguish  the  enforceable  from  the  un- 
enforceable agreement 3 

First  felt  in  connection  with  the  action  of  debt — quid  pro  quo        .  3-4 

"  Consideration  "  used  to  express  the  pacts  which  would  make  an 

agreement  enforceable  by  assumpsit 4 

Consideration  in  the  Chancery 4-5 

Not  a  technical  word  in  the  first  half  of  the  sixteenth  century        .  5-6 

In  the  latter  half  of  the  sixteenth  century  acquires  the  technical 
meaning  of  the  circumstances  necessary  to  make  an  agreement 

enforceable  by  assumpsit 6-7 

Other  influences  affecting  the  doctrine  ......  7-8 

Consideration  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries        .        .         .  8-25 

Different  kinds  of  considerations 9- n 

Mutual  promises g 

A  precedent  debt .  9-10 

Detriment  to  the  promisee      .......  10-11 

Need  not  move  to  the  promisor  but  must  move  to  the  promisee     .  n-13 

A  result  of  the  form  of  the  action  of  assumpsit        ...  n 

Why  the  principle  was  not  firmly  grasped  at  this  period         .  12-13 

Maybe  executory  or  executed  but  cannot  be  past          .         .         .  13-17 

Executed  and  past  consideration 14-15 

Services  done  on  request 15 

Confusion  in  statement  of  the  rule — admission  of  exceptions  to 

the  rule  that  consideration  cannot  be  past         .        .        .  16-17 

Need  not  be  adequate  but  must  be  certain 17-18 

ix 


CONTENTS 


wholly 


to  per 


Must  be  an  act  of  some  value  in  the  eye  of  the  law 

Forbearances  to  prosecute  a  groundless  claim 

Promises  to  release  for  promises  to  pay  an  existing  debt 
or  in  part 

Promises  in  consideration  of  performance  or  promises 
form  a  contract  with  a  third  person 
Summary  of  development  during  these  centuries    . 
Consideration  in  the  eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  centuries 

Character  of  this  development 

Its  technical  basis 

New  ideas     ......... 

Moral  obligation 

Influence  of  mercantile  law 

Continued  influence  of  the  idea  of  moral  obligation  in  early 

teenth  century        ...... 

Results  of  these  ideas 

The  settlement  of  the  modern  doctrine 

Why  the  eighteenth-century  theories  were  rejected 
Rann  v.  Hughes    ....... 

Bosanquet  and  Puller's  note .        .         . 

Its  influence  ....... 

The  new  pleading  rules  of  1834     .... 

The  results  of  Eastwood  v.  Kenyon 

Motive  and  consideration        .... 

The  definition  of  past  and  executed  consideration 

Must  move  from  the  promisee 
Payment  or  promises  to  pay  a  less  sum  than  is  due 
Promises  to  perform  an  existing  contractual  duty  . 

"  Cause  "  and  consideration 

The  continental  development  of  the  "  Cause  " 

Its  advantages  and  disadvantages .... 

Affinities  to  Lord  Mansfield's  views 

Results  of  the  rejection  of  those  views  . 

Why  the  doctrine  of  consideration  is  an  anachronism 

Suggestions  for  the  law  of  the  future     . 

§  2.  The  Invalidity,  Enforcement,  and  Discharge  of  Contracts 
In  this  period  we  see  only  the  origins  of  these  rules 

Invalidity 

Causes  of  invalidity 

Those  arising  from  the  nature  of  an  agreement 
Those  arising  from  incapacity  of  parties 

Illegality  of  object 

Severance  of  legal  from  illegal  stipulations 
Where  a  stipulation  is  not  obviously  illegal 
Statute  and  common  law 

Public  policy 

Contracts  in  restraint  of  trade  . 
Impossibility  ....... 

Promises  absolutely  or  legally  impossible 
Unconditional  promises   .... 

Later  modifications  of  the  law 
Alteration  of  a  contract  under  seal . 
Statutory  provisions         ..... 

The  effects  of  these  causes  of  invalidity 
Void,  voidable  and  unenforceable  . 
Why  these  differences  have  been  obscured 
The  effects  of  fraud  and  misrepresentation  . 
How  they  were  regarded  at  this  period  . 
Give  rise  to  action  for  deceit  or  breach  of  warranty,  but  do 

not  invalidate  a  contract 
Chandelor  v.  Lopus         ..... 

Development  of  the  idea  of  breach  of  warranty 


CONTENTS  xi 

PAGE 

Actions  on  the  contract  for  breach  of  warranty      ...  70 

How  the  modern  law  will  develop 7° 

Enforcement 7°-76 

The  nature  of  the  problem 70-71 

Rules  originating  in  actions  of  debt  and  covenant         .         .         .  71-72 

Applied  to  assumpsit •  72_73 

Rules  as  to  when  promises  were  dependent  and  when  independent  73 

Hardship  of  these  rules 73"74 

Growth  of  idea  that  conditions  might  be  concurrent     .        .        .  74-75 

Beginnings  of  the  modern  law      ......  75 

Rules  originating  in  the  distinction  between  special  assumpsit  and 

assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit 75-7^ 

Cutter  v.  Powell 76 

Discharge 77*87 

Breach 77-78 

Conditions,  warranties,  and  warranties  ex  post  facto     ...  77 

Treatment  of  fraud  and  misrepresentation 77-78 

Refusal  to  perform  and  impossibility  created  by  a  party  to  the 

contract 78 

Performance  or  tender  thereof 78-80 

Performance  of  the  act  promised 78 

Payment 79 

Where  the  payment  is  to  be  by  instalments    ...  79 

Tender  of  goods  or  money     . 79-8o 

Agreement 80-87 

The  Roman  rule  and  English  law 80 

The  operation  of  a  contract  under  seal 80-81 

The  operation  of  a  simple  contract 81-85 

Will  not  discharge  a  contract  under  seal          .        .        .  81-82 

When  the  simple  contract  is  executory    ....  82 
When  one  of  the  parties  has  done  his  part — accord  and 

satisfaction 82-84 

Uncertainty  of  the  law 84-85 

The  novation          .        • 85-87 

Not  possible  in  the  Middle  Ages 85-86 

Introduction  and  development 86-87 

Summary — The  influences  which  were  shaping   the   growth   of  the 

law 87-88 

§  3.    QUASI-CONTRACT 8S-9S 

Mediaeval  origins  in  debt  and  account 88 

The  influence  of  indebitatus  assumpsit 88-89 

Other  influences  which  have  helped  to  make  this  branch  of  law  .         .  89 

The  extension  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  cover  the  field  of  debt  .         .  8g-g2 

Used  to  enforce  duties  not  resting  on  agreement   ....  90 

Holt's  opposition 90-91 

His  failure  to  stop  this  development 91-92 

The  extension   of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  remedy  cases  of  unjust 

enrichment        ..........  92-96 

Could  not  be  used  for  this  purpose  in  the  seventeenth  century       .  92 

Tendency  of  eighteenth-century  developments       ....  92 

Failure  of  consideration 93-94 

Payment  to  a  person  to  whom  the  money  is  not  due     ...  94 

Recovery  from  persons  who  had  wrongfully  taken  the  money       .  94-96 

The  beginnings  of  the  modern  law 96-98 

Want  of  principle  in  the  law          .......  96 

Lord  Mansfield's  generalization 97 

Did  not  cover  all  cases 97-98 

Effect  of  the  abolition  of  the  forms  of  action  on  this  branch  of 

the  law  ...........  98 


xii  CONTENTS 

CHAPTER  IV 

The  Law  Merchant 

page 

I.  Commercial  Law 99-245 

§  1.  Usury  and  the  Usury  Laws 100-113 

Need  for  regulating  the  activities  of  money  lenders      ....  100-101 

The  rationale  of  the  mediaeval  prohibition  of  usury       ....  101 

Mediaeval  English  law  was  based  on  these  ideas 101-102 

Legislation  against  usury 102-103 

The  distinction  between  legal  and  illegal   payments  for   the   use  of 

money 103 

Payments  to  compensate  for  damnum  emergens  or  lucrum  cessans      .  103 

Applications  of  this  principle 104 

The  contractus  trinus 104-105 

Rent  charges  and  leases  at  nominal  rents 105-106 

State  debts  and  montes  pietatis 106 

Why  the  general  prohibition  was  still  maintained         ....  106-107 

Its  weakening  created  a  difficult  problem 108 

Legislation  of  the  early  sixteenth  century 108-109 

The  statutes  of  1571  and  1623 109-110 

Wilson's  opposition  to  this  legislation no 

Later  discussions .  iio-in 

Emergence  of  the  economic  point  of  view in 

Modified  by  the  council  and  equity in 

Later  legislation 112 

The  change  in  the    organization    of   industry    which    caused    this 

legislation 112 

Its  effects  on  the  growth  of  modern  commercial  law    ....  112-113 

§  2.  Negotiable  Instruments 113-176 

Mediaeval  origins  and  continental  development 1 13-146 

Features  of  negotiability  in  modern  law 113-114 

The  early  documents  and  the  bill  of  exchange       ....  114 

The  early  documents 115- 126 

Why  negotiability  was  impossible  in  early  law       .         .        .  115 
Documents  authorizing  payment  to  the  creditor's  nominee 

who  produces  the  document 115-116 

The  variety  of  these  documents 116 

Known  in  France  and  England 116 

They  obviate  the  difficulty  of  representation  for  purposes  of 

litigation 116-117 

They  made  assignment  possible  and  gave  the  assignee  a  better 

position  than  the  assignor 117-118 

They  obviated  the  difficulty  that  a  right  does  not  admit  of 

traditio 118-119 

Legal  theory  was  at  first  hostile  to  the  development  of  these 

documents 119 

Treatment  of  clauses  in  favour  of  a  creditor's  nominee  .        .  119-120 

Their  disappearance 121 

Treatment  of  clauses  in  favour  of  the  producer  or  the  bearer 

of  these  documents 121-123 

Why  the  bearer  lost  his  independent  right  of  action         .  123-124 

Hence  these  documents  loose  their  negotiable  character          .  124-125 

Resulting  inconveniences         .......  125 

French  legislation 125-126 

The  origin  and  development  of  the  bill  of  exchange       .        .        .  126-145 

The  mediaeval  contract  of  cambium 126-131 

Its  nature 126 

Cambium  minutum 126-127 

Cambium  siccum  and  fictivum 127-128 

The  contract  to  transport  money 128 


CONTENTS  xiii 

PAGE 

The  part  played  by  the  exchangers  and  bankers      .        .  128-130 
The  origins  of  bilk  of  exchange  and  banking  .        .        .  130 
This  form  of  the  contract  was  used  by  the  Italian  mer- 
chants in  England 130-131 

The  machinery  used  to  give  effect  to  the  contract  of  cambium  131-140 

The  form  of  the  earliest  bills  of  exchange        .        .        .  131 

Known  in  early  fourteenth  century 132 

Their  origin  in  instrumenta  ex  causa  cambii  and  letters  of 

payment 132 

Not  derived  from  Roman  law 132-133 

Theory  of  an  Arabic  origin 133-134 

Theories  of  Freundt  and  Val£ry 134-136 

The  formal  instrumentum  drops  out        ....  136-137 

The  letter  of  payment  is  the  bill  of  exchange  .        .        .  137 

The  parties  to  the  bill 137 

Relations  of  payee  of  money  to  drawer  who  has  received  it  137 

Relations  of  drawer  and  drawee 138 

Relations  of  acceptor  and  payee 138-139 

Relations  of  payee  and  drawer 139-140 

The  bill  of  exchange  becomes  a  contract  sui  generis,  but 

not  as  yet  negotiable 140 

The  development  of  the  negotiable  character  of  the  bill  of  ex- 
change           140-145 

The  clause  to  the  payee  or  order 141 

Indorsement 141 

Process  by  which  it  became  indefinitely  assignable  by 

repeated  indorsements 141-143 

Relations  of  the  various  indorsees 143 

Presumption  that  the  acceptor  has  received  value  .        .  143 

Enlargement  of  this  presumption 143-144 

Effect  on  the  older  documents 144 

Bills  of  exchange  the  type  and  model  of  negotiable 

instruments 144-145 

Negotiability  and  legal  theory 145-146 

Introduction  into  England  and  development  in  the  common  law          .  146-177 

Lines  of  development 146-147 

The  older  instruments 147-151 

English  lawyers  treat  them  in  the  same  way  as  the  continental 

lawyers 147 

Known  in  the  court  of  Admiralty 147-148 

Malynes's  account  of  them 148-149 

Methods  by  which  they  were  made  assignable       .        .        .  149-150 

Advantages  of  this 150 

Legality  of  these  methods  not  recognised  by  the  common  law  150-151 

The  bill  of  exchange 151-170 

Reception  of  foreign  doctrine          .        .        .         .        .        .  151 

The  bill  of  exchange  in  mercantile  practice    ....  152-159 

Early  specimens  of  these  bills 152-153 

The  parties  thereto  the  same  as  abroad    ....  153 

How  made  assignable 153-154 

Comparison  with  method  used  in  case  of  the  older  instru- 
ments         154 

Bills  made  payable  "  to  the  bringer  thereof"  .        .        .  154-155 

Marius's  book 155 

Shows  that  these  bills  were  becoming  negotiable  155-156 

Comparison  with  English  and  continental  law          .  156-157 

Bills  to  order  and  bearer 157 

The  title  of  the  bona  fide  holder 157 

The  presumption  of  consideration 157-158 

Inland  and  outland  bills 158 

The  parties  to  a  bill rs8 

Confused  by  English  lawyers  with  the  older  instruments  159 


XIV 


CONTENTS 


The  bill  of  exchange  in  English  law 

Assumpsit  used  to  enforce  the  rights  of  the  parties  thereto 

Difficulties  in  statement 

How  obviated 

The  parties  to  the  bill     . 

Relations  of  the  payer  of  money  to  the  drawer  who  has  re 

ceived  it . 
Relations  of  drawer  and  drawee 
Relations  of  acceptor  and  payee 
Relations  of  payee  and  drawer 
Assignability  of  the  bill  of  exchange 

Bearer  instruments 
The  title  of  the  bona  fide  holder 

The  assignee  of  a  thief    . 
The  presumption  of  value 
The  application  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration 
Theory  that  bills  are  in  the  nature  of  contracts  under  seal 
Peculiarities  of  the  English  development 

Promissory  notes 

Early  cases  recognize  their  negotiability 
Notes  issued  by  the  goldsmiths 
Holt's  decisions 
The  statute  of  Anne 
Explanation  of  Holt's  decisions 
The  effects  of  the  statute  of  Anne 


§  3.  Banking 

The  money  changers  were  the  earliest  bankers 
Due  to  same  economic  causes  as  gave  rise  to  the  bill  of 
Fully  developed  in  Italy  in  the  fourteenth  century 
Scope  of  the  business  of  the  bankers    . 
They  facilitate  the  adjustment  of  accounts    . 
They  finance  undertakings    ..... 
;   The  growth  of  the  bank's  political  importance 

Need  for  state  control 

State  banks  at  Venice  and  elsewhere    . 

States  become  debtors  to  banks — Genoa  and  Venice 

Decline  of  private  banking 

Description  of  Marquardus 

Description  of  Malynes 

A  state  bank  advocated  in  England 

Foundation  of  private  banking — the  goldsmiths     . 

Why  no  public  bank  was  founded  till  the  Revolution 

Foundation  of  the  bank  of  England 

Its  services  to  the  state  and  to  trade 

Banking  in  English  law  of  this  period  . 

Cheques  and  bank  notes         .... 

How  far  negotiable 

Their  operation  in  discharging  a  debt    . 

The  banker's  obligation  on  his  notes     . 

§  4.  Commercial  Societies      ..... 
Growth  of  the  commercial  societies  known  to  modern 
Early  forms  of  commercial  association 

The  gild 

Influence  of  the  gilds  on  the  law  of  partnership 
The  commenda     ...... 

Why  not  known  in  England  till  introduced 

.  1907 

The  societas  ...... 

The  firm  a  separate  person     . 

Why  not  recognized  as  such  in  English  law 

Influence  of  the  idea  on  English  law 


exchange 


by 


the  Act  of 


CONTENTS  xv 

PAGE 

Application  of  the  corporate  idea  to  commercial  societies    .        .         .  199-205 

Why  corporate  form  was  desirable 199 

Some  early  charters 199-200 

Purposes  for  which  incorporation  was  at  first  sought     .        .        .  200-202 

Its  commercial  advantages 202-203 

The  personal  liability  of  the  corporators 203-204 

Leviations  and  subrogation 204 

How  this  liability  could  be  limited         .....  204-205 

Combination  of  the  advantages  of  the  societas  and  the  commenda  205 

The  companies  and  partnerships  of  the  seventeenth  century         .        .  206-222 

The  rise  of  the  joint  stock  company 206-213 

Joint  stock  and  regulated  companies 206-207 

Italian  origin  of  the  joint  stock  principle         ....  207-208 

State  loans  and  joint  stock  companies 208 

Origins  of  different  companies  in  England      ....  208-209 
Effect  of  changed  economic  conditions  on  some  of  these 

companies 209-210 

The  South  Sea  and  Hudson  Bay  companies  ....  210 

The  East  India  Company 210-21 1 

Ideas  underlying  the  incorporation  of  the  bank  of  England     .  211 

Capital  lent  to  the  state  used  as  a  fund  of  credit      .        .        .  211-212 

Application  of  this  idea  to  the  South  Sea  Company        .        .  212-213 

Commercial  and  legal  consequences 213-219 

Economic  and  political  consequences 213-214 

Growth  of  a  market  for  stocks  and  shares       ....  214 

The  shady  side  of  joint  stock  enterprise          ....  214-215 

Few  ascertained  rules  of  law 215 

Line  between  corporate  and  unincorporate  societies  not    . 

clearly  drawn 215 

Their  powers  not  limited  by  their  charters     ....  215-216 

This  limitation  established 216 

Accounts  kept  irregularly 216-217 

Problems  of  the  dissolved  or  amalgamated  company      .        .  217 

Law  of  partnership  still  rudimentary 217-218 

Chances  of  fraud  increased  by  the  vagueness  of  the  law        .  218 

The  Government  and  the  South  Sea  Bubble           .        .        .  218-219 

The  Bubble  Act  and  its  effects 219-222 

The  main  defects  of  the  Act 219-220 

Its  provisions         .........  220 

Its  good  and  bad  results          .......  220-221 

Problems  arising  on  the  repeal  of  the  Act      ....  221 

The  modern  history  of  these  topics  begins  with  this  Act         .  222 

§  5.  Agency 222-229 

Agency  not  known  in  primitive  bodies  of  law       ....  222 

The  growth  of  a  law  of  agency 222-223 

The  mediaeval  law 223-224 

Commercial  agents 224 

Brokers 224-225 

Factors 225-226 

Factors  and  servants      ........  226 

Mercantile  practice  little  known  to  the  lawyers      ....  226-227 

Law  of  master  and  servant  not  distinguished  from  the  law  of 

principle  and  agent 227 

Slow  development  of  law  of  commercial  agency   ....  227-228 

Development  in  the  Chancery  and  at  common  law        .        .         .  228-229 

§  6.  Bankruptcy 229-245 

The  personal  character  of  the  debtor's  obligation  in  early  law      .         .  229 

Development  of  a  law  of  bankruptcy  in  Italy 229-230 

History  of  a  creditor's  remedies  in  England 230-231 

Why  constraint  of  the  debtor's  person  became  a  usual  remedy    .        .  231 

Results  of  this 231-232 

VOL.  VIIL— b 


XVI 


CONTENTS 


Its  inadequency  to  meet  commercial  needs 
The  law  modified  in  favour  of  the  unfortunate  debtor 
The  work  of  the  Council 
The  statutes  .... 

Their  ineffectiveness 
Measures  taken  against  dishonest  debtors 
The  work  of  the  Council 
The  bankruptcy  legislation    . 

Henry  VIII. 's  statute     . 

The  statutes  of  1571,  1604,  and  1623 

Persons  who  can  become  bankrupt 

Acts  of  bankruptcy 

Jurisdiction  in  bankruptcy 

Powers  of  the  commissioners  . 

Duties  of  the  commissioners   . 

Assets  available  for  distribution 

Effect  on  the  bankrupt's  liability    . 

Policy  of  these  statutes  . 

Control  of  the  commissioners  . 

The  common  law  decisions     . 

The  work  of  the  court  of  Chancery 

Partnership  cases  .... 

The  vendor's  lien  .... 

Stoppage  in  transitu 
The  defects  of  the  law  .... 
Causes  of  these  defects 
State  of  the  law  in  the  early  nineteenth  century 

Maritime  Law 

Ownership  and  possession  of  ships 

Methods  of  acquisition  . 

Claims  against  a  ship     . 

The  rights  of  co-owners  inter  se     . 
The  master  and  crew  .... 

The  ordinary  complement  of  a  ship 

The  powers  of  the  master 

The  relations  of  master  and  owner 

The  liability  of  the  master  for  the  torts  of  his  employes 

The  liability  of  the  owner  for  the  torts  of  the  master  or  crew 

The  influence  of  these  rules  on  the  common  law 

The  relations  of  master  and  crew  . 
The  contract  of  carriage 

The  different  forms  of  the  contract 

The  charter  party 

The  bill  of  lading 

Liabilities  of  the  masters  or  owners 

The  difference  between  the  common  law  and  the 

Liability  to  pay  freight  and  wages 

Duties  of  the  charterer 

Characteristics  of  some  of  the  cases  of  this  period 
Some  incidents  of  the  contract  of  carriage     . 

Bottomry  and  respondentia 

Average 

Collision 

Salvage 

The  maritime  lien  ..... 


III.  Insurance 

The  place  of  the  contract  in  the  law  of  this  period 
The  origin  of  the  contract  of  marine  insurance 
Marine  insurance  is  the  earliest  variety 
Anticipations  in  Greek  and  Roman  law 
The  Ofncium  Robarie  at  Genoa    . 
Stipulations  as  to  risk  in  the  thirteenth  century 


Admiralty 


rules 


232-233 
233-236 
233-234 
234-235 

236 
236-245 

236 
236-240 
236-237 
237-240 

237 
237-238 

238 
238-239 

239 
239-240 

240 

240 
240-241 

241 
241-242 
242-243 

243 

243 
243-244 
244-245 

245 

245-273 
246-248 

246 
246-247 
247-248 
248-254 

248 
248-249 
249-250 
250-251 
251-252 
252-253 

253-254 
254-261 

251-255 

255 

255-257 

258 

258-259 

259-260 

260 

260-261 

261-273 

261-263 

263-265 

266-269 

269-270 

270-273 

273-298 

273 
274-283 

274 

274-275 

275 

275 


CONTENTS  xvii 

PAGE 

Insurances  disguised  as  sales  or  loans  to  evade  prohibition  of  usury  275-276 

The  earliest  insurance  contract 276 

Modelled  on  the  maritime  loan 277 

Later  modelled  on  a  sale — consequences  of  this    ....  277-278 

Growth  of  insurance  business  in  Italy    ......  278 

Emerges  as  an  independent  contract 278 

Forms  of  the  contract 279 

Rules  which  governed  it         .......  279-281 

Italian  and  Spanish  legislation  as  to  its  validity      ....  281-283 

Its  introduction  into  and  its  development  in  England     ....  283-293 

First  mention  is  in  the  records  of  the  Admiralty  in  1547          .        .  283 

The  practice  then  well  known 283-284 

Its  Italian  origin 284-285 

Regulation  by  the  Council 285 

Grant  of  a  monopoly  right  to  register  insurances    .         .         .  286-287 

Commissioners  to  try  insurance  cases 287 

This  tribunal  was  not  a  success 288 

The  statutory  court  to  try  London  insurance  cases        .         ...  289 

Why  it  failed 289-290 

Slow  development  of  insurance  law 290 

Rules  developed  in  the  Admiralty 290-291 

Rules  developed  by  the  common  law  courts  and  the  Chancery       .  291-292 

Defects  of  the  procedure  of  these  courts 292-293 

No  progress  made  in  the  seventeenth  century        ....  293 

The  origins  of  other  forms  of  insurance 294-298 

Insurances  against  risks  of  transport  by  land 294 

Fire  insurance       .........  294 

Legal  differences  between  insurances  against  risks  to  property  and 

risks  to  the  person 295 

Life  and  accident  insurance  are  not  as  yet  developed     .         .         .  295-296 

Insurances  against  specified  risks  to  the  person      ....  296 

As  yet  they  were  undeveloped 296-297 

These  contracts  were  known  in  England 297-298 

Signs  of  fresh  developments 298 

Mode  in  which  the  foundations  of  English  commercial  and  maritime  law 

had  been  laid  in  this  period 298-299 

Absorption  of  this  new  jurisdiction  needed  to  ensure  the  supremacy  of 

the  common  law 299 

Commercial  law  is  beginning  to  rival  the  land  law  in  importance           .  299 

Effects  of  this  on  the  future  development  of  the  common  law        .        .  299-300 

CHAPTER  V 
Crime  and  Tort 

Influences  which  have  shaped  the  development  of  the  law   ....  301-302 

The  contribution  of  the  common  law 302-305 

Homicide 3°3-3°4 

Larceny 3°4 

Burglary 3°4-3°5 

Arson 3°5 

Principals  and  accessories 3°5 

Misdemeanour  and  tort         .        .         .        .         .        .         .         .  3°5 

Effects  of  combination  of  doctrines  originating  in  the  Star  Chamber 

and  those  originating  in  the  common  law  .....  3°6 

The  distinction  between  crime  and  tort 3°6 

Summary  of  these  influences 3°6-3°7 

§  i.  Constructive  Treason  and  Other  Cognate  Offences      .        .  3°7-333 

Constructive  treason 3°7-322 

Edward  III.'s  statute 3°7 

Adhering  to  the  king's  enemies 3°7_3°8 

Compassing  or  imagining  the  king's  death 3°9-3xS 


xviii  CONTENTS 

PAGE 

The  offence  is  the  intention  to  kill 309 

The  mediaeval  cases       ........  309 

In  the  sixteenth  century  extensions  are  legislative  and  not  con- 
structive ..........  309-310 

The  inadequacy  of  the  statute  and  dangers  of  the  state  .        ,  310 

The  vagueness  of  the  statute 310-311 

The  proof  of  the  intention  to  kill 311 

The  constructive  extension  of  the  late  sixteenth  and  early 

seventeenth  centuries 311-312 

Limitations  then  put  on  this  extension     .....  312-313 

These  limitations  not  wholly  logical 313-314 

Progress  of  the  doctrine  in  the  latter  half  of  the  seventeenth 

century    ..........  314-316 

How  far  accepted  after  the  Revolution 316-318 

Its  application  at  the  end  of  the  eighteenth  century        .         .  318 

Levying  war  against  the  king 318-321 

A  conspiracy  to  levy  war  is  not  within  the  statute  .        .         .  318-319 

Wide  interpretation  of  the  phrase  "  levying  war  "  .         .         .  319-320 

Accepted  after  the  Revolution        ......  320-321 

The  later  history 321-322 

Offences  cognate  to  treason 322-331 

The  change  in  the  conception  of  treason  gives  rise  to  these  offences.  322 

Misprision  of  treason 322-324 

Unlawful  assemblies,  routs  and  riots 324-331 

Definitions 324 

The  nature  of  riot  and  unlawful  assembly       ....  325-326 

Evolution  of  the  law  as  to  unlawful  assembly          .        .        .  326-327 

Repeal  of  the  earlier  legislation  as  to  riot        ....  327 

Effect  of  this  on  the  distinction  between  riot  and  treason        .  327-328 

The  Riot  Act 328-329 

The  liability  of  rioters     ........  329-330 

The  position  of  those  who  seek  to  suppress  riots     .         .         .  330-331 

Why  the  law  on  these  matters  was  rightly  severe         ....  331-332 

Its  success 332 

Helped  by  other  developments  in  the  criminal  law        ....  333 

§  2.  Defamation 333-378 

When  a  crime  and  when  a  tort 333 

Why  it  is  both  a  crime  and  a  tort          .......  333-334 

The  anomaly  of  the  distinction  between  libel  and  slander     .         .         .  334 

The  early  history  of  defamation 334-335 

Defects  of  the  common  law  remedy 335 

Aggravated  by  the  action  of  the  courts 335-336 

Developments  made  by  the  Star  Chamber 336 

Combination  of  these  developments  with  common  law  doctrines.        .  336 

Defamation  as  a  crime 336-346 

Varieties — against  a  private  person  or  the  government.         .        .  336-337 

The  various  sorts  of  indictable  words  or  writings  ....  337 
Law  as  to  seditious  words  or  writings  determined  by  current  views 

as  to  relation  of  rulers  and  subjects 337-338 

At  this  period  the  ruler  is  regarded  as  the  superior  of  the  subject.  338 

Star  Chamber  principles  applied  in  the  common  law  courts  .         .  338-340 

Definition  of  a  seditious  libel 340-341 

Effect  of  the  expiration  of  the  Licensing  Act        ....  341 

The  definition  of  the  offence  is  not  changed 341 

Was  a  seditious  or  malicious  intent  essential  ?      .         .         .         .  341-342 

Presence  of  the  jury  makes  the  question  important       .         .        .  342-343 

The  law  of  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century   .         .        .  343-345 

The  eighteenth-century  controversy 345 

The  law  is  undeveloped   on   many  points  in   the   seventeenth 

century 346 

Defamation  as  a  tort 346-378 

Early  history  of  the  common  law  action  for  defamation        .         .  346-361 


CONTENTS  xix 

PAGE 

Nature  and  scope  of  the  action 346-347 

When  defamation  is  actionable  per  se 347-35° 

When  otherwise  actionable 35°-35x 

Slander  of  title 351-352 

Torts  analogous  to  slander  of  title 352 

Discouragement  of  the  action  by  the  judges  ....  353 

Words  actionable  per  se  restrictively  construed       .         .  353-355 

The  doctrine  of  mitior  sensus .         .        .        •         •         •  355-35° 
Restrictive  rules  as  to  liability  for  the  repetition  of  a 

slander ,•        •  357 

Restrictive  rules  as  to  the  kind  of  damage  for  which  the 

action  lay 357-35° 

What  damage  is  the  natural  and  probable  consequence 

of  the  defamation 35° 

Effects  on  the  law 35 0-301 

The  origin  of  the  difference  between  libel  and  slander  .        .         .  36l-3°7 

Problems  raised  by  the  abolition  of  the  Star  Chamber   .         .  361-362 
Were  various  offences  treated  as  crimes  by  the  Star  Chamber 

also  torts? 3«2"3J3 

If  so,  what  was  the  nature  of  the  tort  ?  3°3-3°4 
Why  written  defamation  was  treated  differently  from  spoken 

defamation 3^'3A 

Good  results  of  this  development 365-3°° 

Its  evil  results 3°°-3°7 

The  historical  relation  of  the  torts  of  libel  and  slander  .         .  367 

The  origin  of  some  essential  characteristics  of  libel  and  slander    .         .  367"37° 

The  words  or  writing  must  be  defamatory     .  3°7-3°8 

The  innuendo 368-369 

The  colloquium •        •  3°9 

The  words  or  writing  must  be  spoken  or  written  of  the  plaintiff    .  37Q-371 

They  must  be  published 37 J 

The  question  of  malice 37 1- 375 

Malice  was  not  the  gist  of  the  action  on  the  case  .        .        .  372 

Held  to  be  a  necessary  ingredient  of  the  crime       .         •        •  372_373 

Elimination  of  this  view 374-375 

Justification 375'376 

Privilege— the  law  on  this  point  was  rudimentary          .        .         .  376-377 

General  conclusions 37° 

§  3.  Conspiracy,  Malicious  Prosecution,  and  Maintenance        .        .  378-402 

Growth  of  the  law  of  conspiracy 378-379 

The  modern  crime  of  conspiracy 379-384 

The  influence  of  the  Star  Chamber 379-38° 

The  gist  of  the  offence 380-381 

The  meaning  of  the  term  "  unlawful  act "      ....  381-382 

Why  a  wide  meaning  was  given  to  the  term  ....  382-383 

Conspiracy  and  public  policy          ......  383 

Aims  of  the  common  law  in  its  treatment  of  conspiracy         .  384 

Malicious  prosecution   .                 385-391 

Development  of  the  mediaeval  remedies          ....  385 

Comparison  of  statutory  writ  and  the  action  on  the  case        .  385-386 

Conspiracies  to  indict  for  treason 386-387 

Conspiracies  to  indict  for  misdemeanours      .         .         .        .  387 

Conspiracies  to  injure  by  abuse  of  legal  process     .        .         .  388 

Acquittal  by  verdict  not  heeded  in  the  action  on  the  case      .  388-389 

The  action  lay  against  one  person  only          .         .        .         •  389 
Elimination   of  the  idea  that  conspiracy  is  the  gist  of  the 

action 3°9-39° 

Restatement  of  the  law  in  Savile  v.  Roberts  ....  39Q-391 

The  modern  tort  of  conspiracy 392397 

Why  this  is  a  modern  question 392 

The  nature  of  the  problem 392"393 

Connection  with  the  old  tort  of  conspiracy     .         .         ...  393 


xx  CONTENTS 

PAGE 

How  far  the  rules  applicable  to  the  crime  apply  to  the  tort    .  393-394 

The  part  played  by  conspiracy  in  constituting  the  tort  .         .  394 

The  two  views  on  this  question 394-396 

The  effect  of  Sorrell  v.  Smith 396-397 

Criticism  of  the  law  as  thus  settled          ....  397 

Maintenance 397-402 

The  mediaeval  development 397-39^ 

Why    the    law    assumed    its    modern    form  by    the  early 

seventeenth  century        .......  398 

Tendency  to  treat  it  rather  as  tort  than  a  crime      .         .         .  398-399 

Was  the  tort  identical  with  the  crime  ? 399  400 

Need  to  prove  special  damage        ......  400-401 

Success  of  the   maintained  litigation   is  not   a  bar  to  the 

action      ..........  401 

Criticism  of  this  rule 401-402 

§  4.  Legal  Doctrines  Resulting  from  the  Laws  Against  Religious 

Non-Conformity 402-420 

In  the  Middle  Ages  religious  non-conformity  was  an  ecclesiastical 

offence 402 

Survival  of  mediaeval  ideas  after  the  Reformation         ....  403 

The  disappearance  of  these  ideas          .......  403-404 

Manner  in  which  this  change  was  effected  ......  404 

The  chief  chronological  stages 404-405 

The    relation    between    law    and    religion    in   the   seventeenth  and 

eighteenth  centuries       ........  406-410 

The  early  seventeenth  century 406 

The  spheres  of  the  ecclesiastical  and  common  law  courts      .        .  406-407 
The  late  seventeenth  century — the  jurisdiction  of  the  common 

law  courts  to  act  as  custodes  morum 407 

Indecency,  profamity,  and  blasphemy  regarded  as  crimes      .         .  407-408 

Christianity  is  regarded  as  part  of  the  law 408 

Apostacy 408 

Principle  underlying  the  law 408-409 

Trusts  for  anti-Christian  purposes  held  to  be  void          .        .         .  409 

In  some  respects  the  law  becomes  more  tolerant  ....  409-410 

But  the  old  principle  was  still  dominant        .....  410 
The  new  situation  created  by  the  repeal  of  the  laws  against  religious 

non-conformity 410-414 

The  Toleration  Act  of  1689 410-411 

Act  in  favour  of  Unitarians  ........  411-412 

Acts  of  1829  and  1832  in  favour  of  the  Roman  Catholics      .         .  412 

Superstitious  uses  not  thereby  legalized          ....  412-413 

Act  in  favour  of  the  Jews 413 

The  position  of  atheists  was  not  affected 413-414 

The  effect  of  this  new  situation  on  legal  doctrine          ....  414-417 
New  view   that  a  reverend  denial   of  Christianity  was   not    a 

criminal  offence       ........  414-415 

The  establishment  of  this  view 415-416 

Trusts  for  non-Christian  or  anti-Christian  purposes  held   to  be 

valid 416 

Effect  of  this  on  ecclesiastical  law 417 

The  effect  of  this  new  doctrine  on  the  older  legislation        .         .         .  417-418 

The  general  trend  of  this  doctrine  in  the  direction  ot  toleration     .         .  418-419 

The  past  development  and  its  possible  consequences  ....  419-420 

§  5.  Lines  of  Future  Development 421-433 

The  differentiation  of  wrongs 421-431 

Wrongs  to  the  person 421-424 

Assault  and  battery 421-423 

False  imprisonment        ........  423 

Unclassified  wrongs  dependent  on  negligence         .         .         .  423-424 

Wrongs  to  property 424-426 

Public  nuisances — when  remediable  by  an  action  in  tort         .  424-425 


CONTENTS  xxi 

PAGE 

What  will  be  accounted  a  nuisance 425-426 

Deceit 426 

Wrongs  to  domestic  relations 427-430 

Influence  of  the  feudal  conception  of  wardship        .        .         .  427-428 

Inadequate  protection  of  a  parent's  rights      ....  428 

The  fiction  of  loss  of  service 428-429 

The  abduction  of  a  servant 429 

The  husband's  rights  to  his  wife's  consortium       .        .         .  430 

The  action  of  criminal  conversation 430 

Wrongs  connected  with  commerce  and  industry   ....  430-431 

Commercial  influences 430 

Why  they  were  not  large  till  the  nineteenth  century     .         .  430-431 

Enlarged  as  the  result  of  nineteenth-century  legislation          .  431 

The  effect  of  these  developments  on  the  law 431-433 

Its  technicality •  431-432 

Increased  importance  of  rules  of  substantive  law          .         .         .  432 

Effect  on  the  principles  of  liability 432"433 

6.  The  Principles  of  Liability 433-482 

Criminal  liability 433-446 

The  requirement  of  mens  rea 433-438 

Both  an  act  and  intent  needed 433-434 

The  nature  of  the  intent 434-435 

Malice  aforethought 435*436 

The  intent  in  manslaughter 436-437 

The  intent  in  larceny 437 

The  effect  of  the  elaboration  of  the  rules  as  to  intent     .        .  437-438 

Incapacities  and  defences      ........  438-445 

Infancy 438-439 

Insanity 439-441 

Drunkenness 441-443 

Coercion 443-444 

Compulsion 444-445 

Necessity 445 

Mens  Rea  and  the  growth  of  the  criminal  law      ....  446 

Civil  liability 446-482 

The  mediaeval  principles 446-447 

Modifications  of  and  additions  to  these  principles          .         .         .  447 

The  conceptions  of  wrongful  intention  and  negligence         .        .  447-464 

The  part  played  by  wrongful  intention           ....  447-448 

Negligence  unknown  in  the  mediaeval  common  law       .        .  449 

The  basis  of  liability  in  the  Middle  Ages       ....  449-450 
Need  to  ascertain  the  proximate  quality  of  the  damage  in 

actions  on  the  case .  450 

Effects  of  approaching  negligence  from  this  angle          .         .  450-451 

First  applied  in  the  sphere  of  contract  and  quasi-contract      .  451-452 

Innkeepers  common  carriers  and  other  bailees        .         .  452-453 
Conception  extended  outside  the  spheres  of  contract  and 

quasi-contract 453 

Application  of  this  idea  to  trespass 453-458 

Line  of  authorities  denying  its  application     .         .         .  453-455 
But  the  current  of  authority  was  setting  in  the  opposite 

direction 455 

Expansion  of  the  idea  of  inevitable  necessity           .        .  455-456 

Rules  applied  to  damage  done  by  animals       .         .         .  456-457 

The  rule  in  Holmes  v.  Mather         .....  457-458 

Survivals  of  the  mediaeval  principle  of  liability      .         .        .  459-464 

Contributory  negligence 459-462 

The  measure  of  damages  for  negligence          .         .         .  462-464 

The  place  of  the  mediaeval  principle  of  liability  in  modern  law     .  464-472 

Interferences  with  possession  or  the  right  to  possess      .         .  465-468 

Tendency  to  mitigate  liability  for  such  interferences        .  465-466 

How  far  this  tendency  has  developed      ....  466 


xxii  CONTENTS 

PAGE 

Acts  amounting  to  asportation,  conversion  or  breaking  of 

closes  are  not  affected  by  it 466-467 

The  reason  for  this 467-468 

The  rule  in  Fletcher  v.  Ry  lands 468-472 

This  rule  was  the  general  rule  in  the  Middle  Ages        .        .  468 

A  stricter  liability  for  dangerous  acts 469 

Liability  for  acts  of  dangerous  animals           ....  469-470 

Cattle  trespass  and  nuisance 470-471 

These  various  influences  are  apparent  in  the  judgment  in 

Fletcher  v.  Ry  lands 471-472 

The  doctrine  of  Employer's  Liability 472-482 

The  mediaeval  law  on  this  topic 472-473 

Continued  till  the  time  of  Holt,  C.J 473-474 

His  decisions  on  this  topic    . 474-475 

Origins  of  the  doctrine 475-477 

The  Roman  influence 475-476 

The  influence  of  exceptional  rules  of  the  mediaeval  common 

law 476-477 

Diverse  explanations  given  of  it   .        .         .         .        .         .         .  477 

The  true  reason  for  it 477-479 

An  unfortunate  result  of  the  late  appreciation  of  the  true  reason  .  479 

The  limits  of  the  employer's  liability 479-482 

Who  is  a  servant  ? 479-480 

The  doctrine  of  common  employment 480-481 

The  over-strictness  of  this  doctrine        .....  481-482 

The  Workmen's  Compensation  Act 482 

Conclusion 482 

Index 483-500 


LIST  OF  GASES 


PAGE 

Acton  v.  Symon 

.      81 

Adams  and  Lambert's  Case     .        .     412 

Admiralty  Commissioners    v.   S.S. 

Amerika 

.     418 

African  Co.  v.  Mason 

.     226 

Aldred's  Case  . 

.     471 

Alexander  v.  Jenkins 

•     350 

Allen  v.  Flood 

•     395.  397.  448 

Allen  v.  Harris 

83,  84 

Andrew  v.  Boughey 

14,  69 

Armes,  the  case  of  . 

•     33o 

Arnolde  c.  Anthonison 

.     258 

Arris  v.  Stukeley 

•      95 

Assievedo  v.  Cambridge 

2QI,  2g2 

Astley  v.  Reynolds  . 

.       94 

Atkins  v.  Banwell   . 

•       33 

Atkins  v.  Hill  . 

28,  30 

Atlas,  the 

.     261 

Atty.  Gen.  v.  Baxter 

.     409 

Atty.  Gen.  v.  Bradlaugh 

.     306 

Atty.  Gen.  v.  Fishmongei 

s  Co.        .    413 

Atty.  Gen.  v.  Pearson 

408,  411 

Atwood's  Case 

.     339, 406 

Atwood  v.  Monger  . 

.        .    388 

Austen  c.  Cattelyn   . 

.     263 

Austin  v.  Culpepper 

•     365 

Austin  v.  Dowlir.g    . 

•    388 

Aylesford  (Earl  of)  v.  Mo 

rris   .         .     in 

B 

Blackwells  (Alderman)  Case 


241,  243,  244 

22,  23,  24,  40 

.     426 

352.  354.  356 

47 


Bagge  v.  Slade 

Baily  v.  Merrell 

Baker  v.  Pierce 

Balfour  v.  Balfour  . 

Bankrupts,  the  Case  of 

Ball  v.  Heskett 

Barber  v.  Fox 

Barber    Surgeons    of    London    v 

Pel  son 
Barham  v.  Dennis   . 
Barham  v.  Nethersal 
Barker  v.  Braham    . 
Barnaby  v.  Rigalt   . 
Barnardiston  v.  Coupland 


240 
26 
3i 


90 
427,  428 
354.  368 

.  388 
160,  162 

.   26 


Barnes  v.  Bruddel  ....  357 
Barnes  v.  Hedley  .  .  .  30,  31 
Barnes  v.  Holloway  .  .  .  369 
Barrow  v.  Wood  ....  59 
Barton  v.  Sadock  .  .  .  227,  228 
Barton  v.  Wolliford  .  .  .291 
Bartonshill  Coal  Co.  v.  Reid  .  477,  479 
Barwick's  Case  ....  13 
Basely  v.  Clarkson  ....  466 
Bates  v.  Grabham  ....  292 
Bathurst  v.  Cox  ....  33g 
Battersey's  Case  ....  54 
Bayley  v.  Homan  ....  84 
Bayly  v.  Merrel  ....  45g 
Beauchamp  (Lord)  v.  Crofts  .  .  376 
Bechuanaland   Exploration    Co.   v. 

London  Trading  Bank  .  .  176 
Beckwith  v.  Nott  ....  79 
Beckwith  v.  Shordike      .         .     456,  466 

Bell  c.  Bryde 260 

Bell  v.  Fox  and  Gamble  .  .  .387 
Bell  v.  Thatcher  ....  349 
Bennett  v.  Allcott  ....  429 
Benson  v.  Morley  ....  360 
Bernina,  The  .  .  .  268,  461,  462 
Beverley's  Case  .  .  52,  439,  441 
Birchley's  Case  ....  355 
Birkmyr  v.  Darnell  ...       66 

Blake's  Case  .  .  .  .  81,  82 
Blisset  v.  Johnson  ....  369 
Blundell's  Trusts,  in  re  .  .  .  417 
Blundell  v.  Winsor  .        .        .     221 

Bodacar  c.  Block  ....  258 
Bold  Buccleugh,  The  .  271,  272,  273 
Bomley  v.  Frazier  .  .  .  164,  169 
Bond  v.  Gonsales  ....  292 
Bonham's  Case  ....  240 
Bonnel  v.  Foulke  ....  94 
Booth  v.  Arnold  ....  350 
Booth  v.  Scale  .  .  .  .355 
Borneley  c.  Troute  .         .        .     258 

Borr  v.  Vandall  ....  226 
Bosden  v.  Thinn  ....  17 
Boson  v.  Sandford  252,  253,  474,  476,  477 
Boss  v.  Litton  ....     456 

Boulton  v.  Arlesden  .  .  475,  476 
Boulton  v.  Banks  .  .  .  .451 
Bourne  v.  Keane  .  .  412,417,418 
Bourne  v.  Mason  .  .  .  n,  12 
Bovey  v.  Castleman        .         •        •       75 


xxju 


XXIV 


LIST  OF  CASES 


PAGE 

Bowen  v.  Hall        ....     448 
Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society 

55,  408,  414,  416,  417,  418,  419 


Box  v.  Jubb    . 

468 

Bracey  v.  Harris 

241 

Bracy's  Case 

239 

Bradburn  v.  G.W.R. 

295 

Bragge  v.  S  tanner  . 

58 

Bray  v.  Hayne 

35o 

Brett  v.  J.S.  and  Wife     . 

18 

Bridge  v.  Cage 

53 

Bridge  v.  Grand  Junction 

Railway 

Co 

461 

Briggs's  Case . 

93 

Briggs  v.  Hartley    . 

414. 

416 

Bright  v.  Cowper    . 

260 

Brikhed  v.  Wilson  . 

79 

British    Columbia    Electric 

Co. 

v. 

Loach 

, 

461, 

462 

Broad  v.  Jollyfe 

58 

Brocas's  Case 

73 

Broke  c.  Maynard  .       283, 

288, 

290, 

291 

Bromage  v.  Prosser 

374 

Bromwich  v.  Lloyd 

161, 

169 

Brook  v.  Montague 

372, 

376 

377 

Brough  v.  Parkins  . 

171 

Brown  v.  London    . 

162 

167 

Brown  v.  Marsh 

168 

Browne  v.  Gibbons 

351 

-352 

Browne  c.  Maye 

246 

Browning  v.  Beston 

1 

Buller  v.  Crips         .       158 

172 

173 

174 

Bunniworth  v.  Gibbs 

17 

Burchell  v.  Slocock 

156 

173 

Burdett  v.  Willett   . 

227 

229 

Burton's  Case 

107 

109 

Bush  v.  Steinman    . 

479 

Bushell's  Case 

343 

Butcher  v.  Andrews 

12 

Butcher  v.  Stapely 

35 

Butterfield  v.  Forrester    . 

461 

Callisher  v.  Bischoffsheim        .         .  19 

Calthorpe's  Case     ....  6 

Calvin's  Case  .....  409 

Came  v.  Moye         ....  290 

Campbell  v.  Hall     .         .         .         .  409 

Canter  v.  Shepheard  ...  79 
Canterbury  (Viscount)  v.  the  Queen 

469,  477 
Carey  v.  Crisp  ....     240 

Cargo  ex  Sultan  .  .  .  .261 
Carlion  v.  Mill  .  .  .  387,  390 
Carpenter  v.  Tarrent  .  .  .  356 
Carter  and    Kenderdine's  Contract, 

in  re 67 

Carter  v.  Downish  .  .  .  157,  163 
Carter  v.  Palmer  ....  172 
Case  v.  Barber         .         .         .  83,  84 

Cavalchant  c.  Maynard   .        .        .     290 


Cavendish  v.  Middleton 
Cayle's  Case    . 
Cayzer  v.  Carron  Co. 
Chamberlain  v.  Prescot 
Chandelor  v.  Lopus 
Chapman  v.  Derby  . 
Chapman  v.  Peers   . 
Chapman  v.  Turner 
Charnock's  Case 
Chesterfield  v.  Janssen 
City  of  York  v.  Toun 
Clark  v.  Pigot 
Clark  v.  Bradlaugh 
Clarke  v.  Shee 
Claxton  v.  Swift 
Clayton's  Case 
Clerk  v.  Taylors  of  Exeter 
Clerke  v.  Martin 
Cocke  v.  Camp 
Coggs  v.  Bernard    . 
Cogley  c.  Taylor     . 
Coke  v.  Fliett  . 
Cole  v.  Turner 
Colgate  v.  Bacheler 
Collen  v.  Wright     . 
Collins  v.  Blantern  . 
Compagnon  v.  Martin 
Cook's  Case     . 
Cook  v.  Wright 
Cooke  v.  Whorwood 
Cooksey  v.  Boverie 
Core's  Case 
Cotteril  v.  Starkey  . 
Cougham  c.  Kindt  . 
Cowan  v.  Milbourn 
Cox  v.  Burbidge 
Cramlington  v.  Evans 
Craven  v.  Knight     . 
Craven  v.  Widdows 
Crawley  v.  Crowther 
Crittal  v.  Horner     . 
Crofts  v.  Brown 
Cromwell's  Case 
Crosse  v.  Gardner    . 
Crouch  v.  Credit  Foncier 
Crow  v.  Rogers 
Crowder  ex  pte 
Culwin,  the  Case  of 
Currie  v.  Missa 
Curry  v.  Walter 
Cutler  v.  Dixon 
Cutter  v.  Powell 
Cutting  v.  Williams 

D 


PAGE 

•  94 

•  452 
.       268 

387,  389 

68,69 

227 

256 

243 
316 
III 
91 
165 
413 

94 

157,  162 

109 

59 

168,  172,  175 

267 

452 

247 

260 

422 

57 

89 

54 

369 

436 

19 

79 

igo,  191 

226 

456,  460 

247 

414,  416 

470 

160,  162,  167,  168 

242 

242 

It  172 

349 

355 

355 

70 

176 

12 


165 


242 

308 

11 

377 

376 

73.  76 

168,  173 


Dacy  v.  Clinch  ....  369 
Dalby   v.    India    and    London    Life 

Assurance  Co 295 

Dale's  Case  .....  68 
Dandy  v.  Turner  ....  293 
Daniell  c.  Nokes      .        ,         .         .267 


LIST  OF  CASES 


XXV 


Darcy  c.  Legg 
Davenant  v.  Midy 
Davies  v.  Mann 
Davis  v.  Saunders 
Davis  v.  Gardiner 
Davis  v.  Lewis 
Daw  v.  Swaine 
De  Costa  v.  De  Pas 
De  Libellis  Famosis 
De  Neronia  c.  Burye 
De  Salizar  c.  Blackman 
Dean  of  St.  Asaph's  Case 
Dearie  v.  Hall 
Deeks  v.  Strutt 
Deguilder  v.  Depeister 
Del  bye  v.  Proudfoot 
Denoyr  v.  Ogle 
Depaba  v.  Ludlow  . 
Dewbery  v.  Chapman 
Diamond  Alkali    Export 

Bourgeois    . 
Dickenson  v.  Watson 
Dictator,  The 


Director  of  Public  Prosecutions  v. 


Beard  . 
Dive  v.  Manningham 
Dixon  v.  Adams 
Docket  v.  Voyel 
Dovaston  v.  Payne 
Dowdale's  Case 
Duckett  c.  Barne     . 
Duncan  v.  Finlater 
Dunlop    Pneumatic 

Selfridge  and  Co. 
Dupleix  v.  De  Rowe 
Duppa  v.  Gerrard    . 
Dutton  v.  Poole 
Duvergier  v.  Fellows 
Dybdale  c.  Holmes 


Tj 


Corp. 


175. 


PAGE 

267 

298 

462 

.   466 

•  351 

•  357 
.  388 

409,  413 

336, 339 

.  258 

.  291 

•  454 
.  125 

•  30 
.  292 
.  290 

290,  297 
.  292 
93 


Evanturel  v.  Evanturel 
Evely  v.  Stouly 
Everard  v.  Hopkins 


PAGE 

55 
422 

73 


Faikiner,  in  re         .         .        .        -47 
Farwell  v.   Boston  and  Worcester 


272 


256 
454 
273 


442,  443 
53,  66.  233 
21 

14 

456 

288 


Co. 


12, 


Railway 
Ferby  v.  Arrosmyth 
Flewellin  v.  Rowe  . 
Flight  v.  Crasden    . 
Flight  v.  Reed 
Flower  v.  Adam 
Floyd  v.  Barker 
Foakes  v.  Beer 
Foord's  Case  . 
Forward  v.  Pittard  . 
Foster  v.  Mackinnon 
Fowler  v.  Sanders  . 
Foxley's  Case . 
Francis  Throgmorton's  Case 
Furtado  v.  Rogers  . 


478,  48 1 

58,59 
86 


33 


37-39 
461 

376 
40 

79 
453 
50,  51 
424 

304 
383,  389 
.     291 


Earle  v.  Oliver 

East  India  Co.  v.  Sandys 

Eastwood  v.  Kenyon 

Eaton  v.  Allen 

Edelstein  v.  Schuler 

Edgcomb  v.  Dee 

Edmunds  v.  Brown  and  Tillard 

Edwards  v.  Hancher 

Egerton  v.  Brownlow 

Elborow  v.  Allen     . 

Elizabeth,  The 

Emerson  c.  De  Sallanova 

Entick  v.  Carrington 

Estwick  v.  Conningsby    . 

Evans's  Case   . 

Evans   v.   The   Chamberlain 

London 
Evans  v.  Heathcote 
Evans  v.  Marlett 
Evans  v.  Walton 


Galizard  v.  Rigault 
2QI I  Gallway  v.  Marshall 
'  Garrard  v.  Hardy    . 

Garret  v.  Taylor 

Gayler  and  Pope  v.  Davies  and  Son 

Gelder  c.  Worelond 

Gelley  v.  Clerk 

Gerrard  v.  Dickinson 

Gibbons  v.  Pepper  . 

Giglis  v.  Welby 

Gloucester  Grammar  School  Case 

Goddard  v.  Garrett 

Goddard  v.  O'Brien 

Good  v.  Cheesman  . 

Goodwin  v.  Robarts 
I  Goram  v.  Fouke 


478] 

47 
91 
90 

29,40 
221 
258 


33-34,  37,  39 
201,  409 
34.  37,  38,  4?    Goring  v.  Goring    . 
354    Gourden  c-  Lovelake 
j  jq  j  Gower  v.  Capper     . 
Graham  v.  Stamper 
Grant  v.  Vaughan  . 
Gray  v.  Jefferies 
Green  v.  Young 
Green  leaf  v.  Barker 
Grinnell  v.  Wells     . 
Guy  v.  Livesey 
Gyllet  c.  Style 


01 


.  72 

.  203 

.  84 
54,55 

•  351 
.  265 

•  253 
.  466 
.  217 
.  411 


4M 

39 

257 

428 


164,  17 


430 
350 
221 
423 
456 
246 
452 
35i 
455 
152 
425 
292 
8=? 


173 


176 
292 
22,83 
260 
72 
223 

3,  176 
427 
291 

10,  21 
429 

43° 

267 


H 

Hadley  v.  Baxendale 
Hales  v.  Petit 
Hall  v.  Hollander   . 


3°4 


463 
433 

428 


XXVI 


LIST  OF  CASES 


PAGE 

PAGE 

Halloway's  Case     . 

•     435 

I 

Handcocke  c.  Payne 

.     267 

Hansard  v.  Robinson 

•     157 

Ive  v.  Chester 

.         52 

Harbert's  Case 

230,  231 

Iveson  v.  Moore     . 

363.  365,  - 

Harding  v.  Bodman 

•     376 

Harford  and  Gardiner's  Case  . 

.       18 

Harman  v.  Delany  . 

•     365 

J 

Harman  v.  Vanhatton 

292,  293 

Harper  v.  Beamond 

.     360 

Jackson  v.  Adams    . 

. 

•     354 

Harrison  v.  Heathorn     . 

.     221 

James  v.  Rutlech  (or  Rutledge) 

Harrison  v.  Thornborough 

•     356 

349, 

355,  368 

Harry  v.  Perrit 

163, 164 

Janson  v.  Driefontein  Mines  Ltc 

•    .      54 

Harvey  v.  Gibbons . 

•       63 

Janvier  v.  Sweeny  . 

•     352 

Hatch  v.  Trayes 

.     167 

Jaques  c.  Hulson    . 

.     258 

Hawkes  v.  Saunders 

28,  30,  36 

Jazawickreme  v.  Amarasuriya 

•       43 

Hawkins  v.  Cardy   . 

.     171 

Jeffereys  v.  Small   . 

.     217 

Hay  v.  Le  Neve 

.     266 

Jefferies  v.  Austin  . 

.     168 

Hayes  v.  Warren    . 

.       16 

Jefferies  v.  Legendra 

.     292 

Haylyn  v.  Adamson 

.     164 

Jelliet  v.  Broad 

58,59 

Heath  v.  Chapman 

•     413 

Jenkins  v.  Turner   . 

.     45i 

Henley  v.  Burstal    . 

•     387 

John  Royley's  Case 

•     303 

Herbert  v.  Towns   . 

.     185 

Johns  v.  Gittings     . 

.     375 

Hern  v.  Nichols 

475,  477 

Johnson  v.  Astell    . 

22 

Hext  v.  Yeomans    . 

•     354 

Johnson  v.  Aylmer  . 

369,  370 

Heyman  v.  R. 

•     375 

Johnson  v.  Collings 

•     157 

Hicksiv.  Palington 

.     265 

Jones  v.  Barkley 

•       74 

Hill  v.  Lewis  .         .       156,  164 

166,  170 

Jones  v.  Brown 

.     428 

Hilsden  v.  Mercer  . 

369.  375 

Jones  v.  Davers 

•     37i 

Hindhaugh  v.  Blakey 

•     157 

Jones  v.  Givin         .       374 

389, 

39o,  39i 

Hinton's  Case 

.     164 

Jones  v.  Hart 

.     260 

Hitchcock  v.  Coker 

.       62 

Jones  v.  Hulton 

.     37o 

Hitchcock  v.  Sedgwick    . 

.     242 

Jonson  c.  Bannister 

253,  254 

Hodge  v.  Vavisour 

■  9,  16 

Jorden  v.  Money 

.       48 

Hodges  v.  Steward 

Joscelin  v.  Skelton 

6 

155,  162,  163,  164 

166,  167 

Josceline  v.  Lassere 

.     167 

Hodsden  v.  Harridge 

.       66 

Joy  v.  Kent     . 

.     263 

Hollins  v.  Fowler    . 

•     467 

Hollis  v.  Briscow    . 

.     36° 

Hollis  v.  Edwards  . 

•      35 

K 

Holmes's  Case 

•    305 

Holmes  v.  Hall 

•       93 

Kaines  v.  Sir  R.  Knightly 

.     2g2 

Holmes  v.  Mather  .        .      457, 

458,  466 

Keeble  v.  Hickeringill     . 

426,  431 

Holstcomb  v.  Rivers 

.     217 

Kemp  v.  Housgoe   . 

.     360 

Holt  v.  Astgrigg 

•     360 

Kempe's  Case 

•     355 

Hopkins  v.  Geary    . 

.     191 

Kenrig  v.  Eggleston 

•     259 

Home  v.  Delapyn   . 

.     269 

Ketsey's  Case 

•       52 

Horton  v.  Coggs 

.     171 

Kiggil  v.  Player 

.     240 

How  v.  Prinn 

•     35o 

Kinder  v.  Taylor 

.     221 

Howard's  (Sir  Robert)  Case     . 

.     297 

King  v.  Lake 

.     364 

Howard  v.  Bell  and  Others     . 

•     326 

Kinge  c.  Gomez 

.     246 

Howard  v.  Wood    . 

•       95 

Kingston  v.  Booth  . 

•     473 

Howlet  v.  Osbourn 

.       92 

Kingston  v.  Preston 

74,  75 

Hulbert  v.  Watts    . 

•       78 

Kinnion  v.  Dacres  . 

•     45i 

Hunlockev.  Blacklowe    . 

.       58 

Knapp  v.  Salsbury 

•     456 

Hunt  v.  Bate  .        .        .        .3 

H»  15. 37 

Knight  v.  German 

•     389 

Hunt  v.  Line  .... 

•     389 

Knight  v.  Rushworth 

10 

Hurford  v.  Pile 

.       82 

Knipe  v.  Jesson 

.     226 

Hurlocke  and  Saunderson  c.  Collett     257 

Huscombe  v.  Standring  . 

•       5i 

Hussey  v.  Jacob      .        .        53 

166,  169 

L 

Hutton's  (Justice)  Case   . 

•     339 

Hyde  v.  Scyssor 

•     430 

Ladyngton  v.  Hussey 

.     258 

Hylein  (or  Heylin)  v.  Hastings 

26,39 

Lake  v.  King 

• 

•     376 

LIST  OF  CASES 


XXVll 


PAGE 

Lamb's  Case 339 

Lambert  v.  Bessey  .  .  .  454,  455 
Lambert  v.  Oakes  ....  156 
Lambert  v.  Pack  .  .  156,  164,  166 
Lamine  v.  Dorrell  ....  95 
Lampleigh  v.  Brathwait  14,  15,  38-39 
Lane  v.  Cotton  .  .  .  474,  477 
Lane  v.  Williams  ....  217 
Langdon  v.  Stokes  ...      82 

Lappage,  in  re  .  .  .  .  247 
Laughter's  Case  ....  63 
Laughter  v.  Pointer  .  .  .  480 
Law  v.  Harwood  .  .  .  351,352 
Law  v.  London  Indisputable  Life  Policy 

Co 295 

Le  Buck  c.  Van  Voisdonck     .        .     259 

Le  Pypre  v.  Farr     ....     293 

Lea  v.  Exelby  ....      78 

Leame  v.  Bray        .        .        .     454,  455 

Lee  v.  Muggeridge  .        .         31.37 

Leneret  v.  Rivet      ....      79 

Leroux  v.  Brown     . 

Lethuliers  Case 

Lewis  v.  Chase 

Lincoln  (Earl  of)  v.  Fysher 

Lincoln  (Earl  of)  v.  Topcliff 

Littlefield  v.  Shee  . 

Lloyd  v.  Grace  Smith  and  Co 

Lloyd  v.  Lee  . 

Longridge  v.  Dorville 

Lorde  c.  Butter 

Lovet  v.  Faulkner  . 

Low  v.  Beard  more 

Ludkyn  c.  Edmunds 

Lumley  v.  Gye 

Lutwidge  v.  Gray  . 

Lynch  v.  Knight 

Lyon  v.  Fishmongers  Co 

Lytt  v.  Ault    . 


Master  v.  Miller 
Maunsell  v.  Hedges 
Mathew  v.  Crass 
Maxim  Nordenfelt  Co. 


•  35 
.  292 

•  27 

•  339 
.  226 

•  37 
.  476 

•  3i 
.  19 
.  267 

•  386 

•  387 
.  246 

29,  43i.  448 

.  260 

348,  357.  358 

.  425 

•  87 


M 


Macintyre  v.  Connell 
Mackalley's  Case    . 
Mackeller  v.  Todderick   . 
Mackonochie  v.  Lord  Penzance 
Maddy's  Case 
Makarell  v.  Bachelor 
Maleverer  v.  Redshaw     . 
Manby  v.  Scott 
Manning  v.  Fitzherbert  . 
Mansell  and  Herbert's  Case 
Manton  v.  Brocklebank    . 
Manwood  and  Burston's  Case 
Marham  v.  Pescod  . 
Marsh  and  Rainford's  Case 
Martin  v.  Boure 
Martin  v.  Crompe   . 
Martin  v.  Sitwell     . 
Martyn  v.  Hind 
Mason  v.  Keeling    . 
Mason  v.  Provident  Clothing  Co 


.  192 
329,  436 

•  53 
.  417 

•  437 

•  52 

•  54 
.   90 

•  390 

•  435 

465,  466 

7 

•  387 

•  15 
159,  160 

.  217 

94.  292 
.   29 

454.  469 
62 


PAGE 

•    65, 398 

.     .     .    48 

•   351 

v.  Nordenfelt 

53.  56,  62 
May  v.  Burdett  ....  470 
Maye  c.  Hawkyns  ....  269 
Mayor  of  Bradford  v.  Pickles .  397,  448 
Mayor  of  Exeter  v.  Trimlet  .  .  91 
Mayor  of  London  v.  Bennet  .  .  185 
Mayor  of  London  v.  Gorry  .  .  90 
Mayor  of  London  v.  Hunt      .  90 

McPherson  v  Daniels  .  .  .  357 
Medina  v.  Stoughton  ...  70 
Meechett  v.  Bradshaw  .  .  .  242 
Meggot  v.  Mills  .  .  .  237,  240 
Mercer  v.  Sparks  ....  372 
Mervyn  v.  Lyds  .  .  .  .18 
Mew  v.  Russell  ....  69 
Mexican  and  South  American  Co., 

in  re  .         .         .         .         .     221 

Meyer  v.  Haworth  .  .  .  -37 
Michel's  Trusts,  in  re  .  .  .  417 
Middleton  v.  Fowler  .  .  .  475 
Mildmay  v.  Standish  .  .  .  351 
Miles  v.  New  Zealand  Alford  Estate 

Co 19 

Milles  v.  Milles  ....  79 
Milman  v.  Dolwell  ....  456 
Mitchel  v.  Reynolds  .  12,  60-61,  62 
Mitchil  (or  Michael)  v.  Alestree 

453.  47o,  473 
Mitten  v.  Faudyre  .  .  .  451,  456 
McNaghten's  Case.  .  .  440,  441 
Mogadara  v.  Holt  ....  161 
Moggridge  v.  Thackwell  .         .     409 

Mogul  Steamship  Co.  v.  McGregor.  396 
Molton  v.  Camroux  53 

Moor  v.  Foster  ....  360 
Morris  v.  Saxelby  ....  62 
Mors  v.  Thacker  .  .  .  .  371 
Morse  v.  Slue.  .  .  .  251,  259 
Morton  v.  Lamb  ....  75 
Moses  v.  Macfarlan         .         .         .       97 

Mouse's  Case 264 

Moyes  v.  Little       ....     241 

.     308,  380 

.     414 


Mulcahy  v.  R. 
Murray  v.  Benbow. 


X 


Nash  v.  Inman  ....  52 
Neville  v.  London  Express  News- 
paper Ltd.  .  362,  363,  400-401 
Newdigate  v.  Davy.  ...  94 
Newman  v.  Zachary  .  .  .  358 
Nichols  v.  Mars  land  .  .  .  468 
Nichols  v.  Raynbred  73 
Nicholson  v.  Sedgwick  .  .  164,  172 
Normanby  (Marquis  of)  v.  Duke  of 

Devonshire 35 

Norris  v.  Palmer     ....     390 


xxvm 


LIST  OF  CASES 


Northampton's  (Earl  of)  Case 
Norton  v.  Jason 
Norton  v.  Simmes   . 


PAGE 

357. 358 
.     428 

•       54 


Oaste  v.  Taylor       .         .         .      160 

162 

Officium  Domini  Regis  c.  Goods  ex 

a  Hamburgh  Ship 

246 

Officium  Domini  Regis  c.  The  Eu- 

genius          ..... 

246 

Ogle  v.  Barnes        .... 

454 

Oldnoll's  Case          .... 

34° 

Omichund  v.  Barker 

409 

Paine  v.  Partrich  ....  425 
Paradine  v.  Jane     ....       64 

Parr  v.  Clegg 416 

Pasley  v.  Freeman  ....  426 
Payne  v.  Beuwmorris  .  .  .  350 
Payne  v.  Porter  .  .  .  385,  388 
Paynter  v.  Williams  .  .  33,  37 
Peacham's  Case  .  .  .  313,315 
Peacock  v.  Rhodes  .  .  .  165,  166 
Pecke  v.  Redman  ....  79 
Pedro  v.  Barrett      ....     393 

Peytoe's  Case 82 

Phillips  v.  Homfray  ...  38 
Pickering  v.  Barkley  .  .  .  291 
Pickering   v.    Ilfracombe    Railway 

Co 54 

Pigot's  Case  .  .  .  .50,  54,  64 
Pillans  v.   Van   Mierop      29,  32,  35,  45, 

47,  168 
Pine's  Case  .  .312,  315,  316,  339 
Pinkney  v.  Hill  ....  217 
Pinnel's  Case  .  .  .20,  21,  80,  81 
Pitt  v.  Smith 53 


Planche  v.  Fletcher 
Plymouth  (Countess  of)  v.  Throg 
morton 

451,  459,  46 


Polemis,  in  re . 

Pollard  v.  Evans 

Pong  v.  Lindsay 

Pope  v.  Lewyns 

Pordage  v.  Cole 

Potter  v.  Pearson 

Poulterers'  Case,  The 

Powell  v.  Hutchins 

Poyntell  c.  De  Billota 

Poynter,  the  Case  of 

Pratt  v.  British  Medical  Association 

Price  v.  Easton 

Price  v.  Jenkings 

Priestley  v.  Fowler  .         .         .     480,  481 

Printing  Co.  v.  Sampson  .         .       56 

Prugnell  v.  Gosse   ...         58,  59 


Q 

PAGE 

Quartz  Hill  Gold  Mining  Co.  v.  Eyre  391 
Quin  v.  Leathern    392,  393,  395,  396,  397 


291 

76 

2,463 

390 

79,  80 

69 

73 

173 

380 

360 

246 

308 

395 
40 

37i 


R 


Racine,  The    .... 

Rainsford  v.  Fenwick 

Ralph  Comwaille,  the  Case  01 

Ram  v.  Lamley 

Ramsey  v.  Brabson 

Rann  v.  Hughes       27,  28,  30,  35 

Ratcliffe  v.  Evans   .       351,352, 

Ravens  c.  Hopton    . 

Raybould,  in  re 

Raylestone  c.  Guerson 

Reech  v.  Kennegal 

Reediev.  L.N.W.R. 

Reeves  v.  Hearne    . 

Reniger  v.  Fogossa  . 

Revell  c.  Bona  Stringar 

R.  v.  Annet     . 

R.  v.  Arnold    . 

R.  v.  Barker    . 


Barnardiston 
Baxter    . 


R.  v.  Beare 

R.  v.  Best 

R.  v.  Bradshaw  and  Others 

R.  v.  Briellat  . 

R.  v.  Carlile    . 

R.  v.  Carr 

R.  v.  Carroll   . 

R.  v.  Casement 

R.  v.  Cassy  and  Cotter 

R.  v.  Cole 

R.  v.  Critchley 

R.  v.  Crohagan 

R.  v.  Cruse 

R.  v.  Crutch!  ey 

R.  v.  Curl 

R.  v.  Dammaree  and  Purchase 

R.  v.  Davis     . 

R.  v.  Dudley  . 

R.  v.  Ellis 

R.  v.  Ernest  Jones  . 

R.  v.  Francklin 

R.  v.  Frost 

R.  v.  Fussell   . 

R.  v.  Gordon  . 

R.  v.  Lord  George  Gordon 

R.  v.  Grey 

R.  v.  Grey  and  Others 

R.  v.  Griepe     . 

R.  v.  Grindley 


Hadfield 
R.  v.  Hale  . 
R.  v.  Hardy 
R.  v.  Harman 
R.  v.  Harris  . 
R.  v.  Harrison 
R.  v.  Harvey   . 


434 


464 
52 
102 
376 
244 
,  36,  168 
357,  365 
.  291 
.  467 
.  246 
.  28 
.  480 

•  39 
441.445 

.  258 
.  408 

•  440 
.  411 

34o,  343 

•  340 
337. 339 
380,  381 

•  3r9 

•  339 

•  413 
340. 343 

•  442 
307,  308 

•  305 

•  237 

•  339 
315.  3i6 

•  444 
.  444 

337.  4°8 
.  320 
.  442 

•  445 

•  326 
.  327 

344.  345 

•  339 

•  327 
.  33g 

320-321 

•  303 
.  381 

•  368 

•  442 

•  440 
.  408 

318,  320 

•  304 
340.  345 

•  339 
.  374 


LIST  OF  CASES 


XXIX 


PAGE 

R.  v.  Hetherington  .         .         .     413 

R.  v.  Hicklin 337 

R.  v.  Holyoake  .  .  .  .415 
R.  v.  Home  Tooke  .        .318,  320 

R.  v.  Huggett  .        .         .        .     303 

R.  v.  Hull        ....     435,  436 

R.  v.  Johnson 305 

R.  v.  Johnson           ....     340 
R.  v.  Journeymen  Taylors  of  Cam- 
bridge   381 

R.  v.  Keite 303 

R.  v.  Kimberty  ....  381 
R.  v.  Kinnersley  ....  380 
R.  v.  Langley  ....  337.  339 
R.  v.  Levett    ....     304,  434 

R.  v.  Lovett 338 

R.  v.  Lynch 308 

R.  v.  M'Growther  ....  444 
R.  v.  Mawgridge  .  .  .  303,  435 
R.  v.  Meade  ....  442,  443 
R.  v.  Messenger  Basely  and  Others  320 
R.  v.  Monkhouse  .  .  .  >  443 
R.  v.  Lord  M  or  ley  ....     303 

R.  v.  Moxon 413 

R.  v.  Munslow        ....     375 

R.  v.  Oneby 303 

R.  v.  Orbell 381 

R.  v.  Owen  .  .  .  312,  315,  316 
R.  v.  Penny  ....  337 
R.  v.  Pinney   .....     330 

R.  v.  Pooley 415 

R.  v.  Lord  Preston  .        .         .317 


R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote  4,  10,  415,  416, 

418 


v.  Raven    . 

v.  Read 

v.  Salisbury 

v.  Sedley    . 

v.  Serne 

v.  Soley 

v.  Starling 

v.  Stratton 

v.  Sudbury 
R.  v.  Sullivan 
R.  v.  Sutton    . 
R.  v.  Taylor    . 
R.  v.  Thorp     . 
R.  v.  Tong 
R.  v.  Topham 
R.  v.  Tutchin  . 
R.  v.  Twisleton  and 
R.  v.  Twyn     . 
R.  v.  Vaughan 
R.  v.  Waddington 
R.  v.  Webb     . 
R.  v.  Winterbotham 
R.  v.  Woolston 
Reynolds  v.  Clarke 
Reynolds  v.  Pinhowe 


Others 


•  304 

•  337 

•  376 
.  407 

•  436 
.  326 

380,  381 
~  445 

•  325 
338 

•  438 

•  339 

•  38i 
314.  323 

•  339 
34i.  344 

.  381 

•  314 
.  308 

•  413 
.  220 

•  339 
408,  410,  414 

•  432 
21 


Reynolds  v.  Shipping  Federation  Ltd.  395 
Richards  and  Bartlet's  Case  .  10,  21 
Richardson  v.  Godwin  .  .  .  243 
Richardson  v.  Saunderson       .        .     269 


Ricket  v.  Metropolitan  Railway  Co.  425 
Ridolphe  c.  Nunez  .         .         .     283 

Ripon  City,  the  .  .  270,  271,  272 
Ritzo  c.  Pignea  ....  258 
River  Wear  Commissioners  v.  Adamson 

456 
Roberts  v.  Tremayne  .  .  .  107 
Robins  and  Co.  v  Gray  .  .  .  452 
Robins  v.  H  ildredon  .  .  .  360 
Rodriguez  v.  Speyer  Bros.  .  .  56 
Roe  v.  Haugh  8r> 

Rogers  v.  Parry  ....  58 
Rogers  v.  Snow  ....  73 
Rose,  Frank  and  Co.  v.  Crompton  Bros. 

47 
Rosindale's  Case     .         .  53 

Rosweil  v.  Vaughan  ...  68 
Royley's  Case  ....     437 

Rudder  v.  Price       .         .  79 

Russell  v.  Corne      .        .         .     429,  430 
Rylands  v.  Fietcher  454,  455,  456,  465, 
468,  469,  470,  471,  472 


Salmon  v.  The  Hamborough  Co.  203,  204 

Samson,  in  re 48 

Saunderson  v.  Richardson  .  •  269 
Savage  v.  Robery  ....  369 
Savignac  v.  Roome  .         .        .    432 

Savile  v.  Roberts     388,  389,  390-391,  393, 

400 
Scotson  v.  Pegg  .  .  .  H,  40,  41 
Scott  v.  Shepherd  .  .  432,  454,  455 
Scutt  v.  Hawkins  . 
Selby  v.  Carrier 
Semayne's  Case 
Sere  and  Eland  v.  Colley 
Seven  Bishops,  Case  of  the 
Seward  v.  Baker 
Shadwell  v.  Shadwell  . 
Sharington  v.  Strotton  . 
Sharpley  v.  Hurrel 
Shelden  v.  Hentley 
Shelley's  Case 
Sheperd  v.  Wakeman 
Sheppard  v.  Maidstone  . 
Sheppard  v.  Wright 
Sherwood  v.  Woodward  . 
Shore  v.  Wilson 
Shrewsbury's  (Countess  of)  Case 
Shuttleworth  v.  Garnet  . 
Sibthorp's  (Doctor)  Case 
Sidenham  and  Worlington's  Case 

6,  14.  15 
Sidney's  (Algernon)  Case  .  315,  3r6 
Simondson  c.  Manelli      .         .         .     247 


.  369 

•  355 

•  325 

•  237 

•   34i.  344 

•   9i 

40,  41 

6 

.  107 

•   165,  171 

•   97 

•  352 

.  226 

.  265 

23,  24 

•  412,  415 

se     451 

90,  91 

•  349 

Sippora  v.  Basset    . 
Skinner  v.  Gunton 
Slade's  Case    .      9, 
Smale  v.  Hammon 
Smith,  in  re 


•  429 
.      389.  393 

16,  28,  37,  89,  90,  gi 

•  352 

•  417 


XXX 


LIST  OF  CASES 


PAGE 

Smith  v.  Airey  ....  75 
Smith  v.  Bromley  ....  94 
Smith  v.  Cranshaw  .  .  .  387 
Smith  v.  Oxenden  ....  226 
Smith  v.  Richardson  .  .  .  373 
Smith  v.  Watson  ....  35 
Somers  v.  House  ....  356 
Somerton's  Case  ....  68 
Sorrell  v.  Smith  .  .  394,  396,  397 
Southcot  v.  Bennet  .  .  .  259 
Southcote's  Case  .  .  226,  259,  452 
Southern  v.  How  .  69,  227,  228,  430 
Southern  Rhodesia,  in  re  .  .  210 
Spanish  Ambassador  v.  Gifford  .  73 
Speerman  v.  Degrave  .  .  .  229 
Spencer  v.  Hemmerde  .  .  .  39 
Spinula  v.  Camby  .  .  .  138,  140 
Sprigwell  v.  Allen  ....  68 
Spysall  v.  Walters  ....  267 
Squire  v.  Johns  ....  241 
Stainbank  v.  Fenning  .  .  .  262 
Stanley  v.  Powell  .  447,  454,  458,  466 
Star  v.  Rookesby  ....  452 
Starke  v.  Cheeseman  .  .  91,  162 
Starkey  v.  Mill  .  .  .  .  13 
Steer  v.  Scoble  ....  388 
Stevens  v.  Savidge  ....  261 
Stewart  v.  Casey  .  .  .  -39 
Stock  v.  Mawson  ....  29 
Stone  v.  Wythipol  .  .  10,  18,  36 
Stoomvaart  Maatschappy  Nederland 
v.  The  P.  and  O.  Steam  Naviga- 
tion Co 266 

Stuart  v.  Wilkins  ....  70 
Sturlyn  v.  Albany  .  .  .  .17 
Sumner  v.  Brady  ....  27 
Sydenham  v.  Keilaway  .  .  .  388 
Sydenham  v.  May  ....  369 
Symonds  v.  Danyell  .  .  .  258 
Symons  v.  Darknoll         .         .         .     259 


Tailors  of  Ipswich,    Case   of  the 


Tanner  v.  Smart 
Tasburgh  v.  Day 
Tassell  v.  Lee 
Tassell  and  Lee  v.  Lewis 
Tatlock  v.  Harris    . 
Taylor's  Case . 
Taylor  v.  How 
Taylor  c.  Pennincke 
Taylor  v.  Perkins    . 
Temperton  v.  Russell 
Tennant  v.  Goldwin 
Thairlwall  v.  G.N.R. 
Thomas  v.  Thomas 
Thompson  v.  Harvey 
Thorley  v.  Kerry 


Thorneton  c. 
ventura 


The  Elizabeth  Bona- 


58,  59 

39 

35i 

157 

191 

87 
408 

37i 

258 

349 
448 

47i 

173 

38 

59 

365,  366 


397. 


254 


PAGE 

Thornton  v.  Howe  ....  416 
Thoroughgood's  Case  .  .  50,  51 
Thorpe  v.  Thorpe  73 

Thurston  c.  More  ....  260 
Tillett  v.  Ward  .  .  .  .456 
Tobin  v.  The  Queen  .  .  .  477 
Tolson  v.  Clark  .  .  .  .18 
Tomkyns  (or  Tomkins)   v.   Barnet 

(or  Bernet) 94 

Tottenham  and  Bedingfield's  Case 


Townsend  v.  Hunt  . 
Traske's  Case 
Trench  v.  Trewin    . 
Treswaller  v.  Keyne 
Trewinian  v.  Howell 
Trowel  v.  Evans     . 
Trueman  v.  Fenton 
Tuberville  v.  Savage 
Tuberville  v.  Stamp 
Tubwomen    v.    The 

London 
Tuff  v.  Warman 
Turnor  v.  Goodwin 
Tweddle  v.  Atkinson 
Tye  c.  Springham  . 


92,94 

15.  16.  37 

407 

73 

82 
28 

192 
26 

422 

•  469,  474.  476 
Brewers    of 

•  •        •     381 

.    461 

.       74 

.      40 

.      254,  271 


Underwood  v.  Hewson  . 


V 


454 


Valentine  v.  Hyde  . 

395 

Vandenanker  v.  Desborough 

241 

242 

Vane's  Case    . 

314 

Vanspike  v.  Cleyson 

377 

Vaughan  v.  Ellis    . 

351 

Vaughan  v.  Menlove 

. 

45o 

Vawse  c.  Bygot 

258 

260 

Veritas,  The   . 

272 

273 

Vernon  v.  Boverie  . 

.      170 

191 

Vicars  v.  Wilcocks . 

358 

Villers  v.  Monsley  . 

. 

365 

w 


Waberley  v.  Cockerel 

82 

Wade's  Case  . 

80 

Wade  v.  Simeon 

19 

Wain  v.  Bailey 

173 

Wainford  v.  Barker 

65 

Wakeman  v.  Robinson   . 

•      454 

456 

Walburn  v.  Ingilby 

221 

222 

Walpole  (Lord)  v.  Lord  Orford 

48 

Waltham  v.  Mulgar 

251 

Ward  v.  Duncombe 

125 

Ward  v.  Evans         .       170, 

190,  191 

475 

Ware  v.  Chappel     . 

• 

72 

LIST  OF  CASES 


XXXI 


Ware   and    De   Freville   v.    Motor 

Trade  Association  .  .  .  395 
Wason  v.  Walter  ....  377 
Waterer  v.  Freeman  .  .  .388 
Wakinv.  Hall  ....  369 
Wayland's  Case  .  .  475,  476,  477 
Weatherston  v.  Hawkins  .  .  377 
Weaver  v.  Cariden  ....  354 
Weaver  v.  Ward  .  .  .  454,  455 
Webb  v.  Beavan  ....  348 
Weedon  v.  Tirnbrell  .  .  .  428 
Weld  Blundell  v.  Stephens  .  .  463 
Welford  v.  Beazely  35 

Wells  v.  Wells  ....  28 
Wennall  v.  Adney  .  .  .36,  37,  38 
West  v.  Shuttleworth  .  412,  413,  417 
Western  v.  Wildy  .  .  .  .291 
Weston  v.  Dobniet  .         .         .     376 

Whelpdale's  Cass  .  .  .  .51 
Whiteheld  c.  Garrarde  .  .  .  264 
Whitehead  v.  Walker  .  .  .156 
Whittingham  v.  Hill  ...  52 
Whorwood  v.  Gybbons  ...  6 
Wild  v.  Middleton  ....  237 
Wilkinson  v.  Downton  .  .  .  352 
Wilkinson  v.  Kitchin  .  .  .  94 
William  Bane's  Cas?  ...  10 
William  Lewson  v.  Kirk  .         .     226 


PAGE 

Williams's  Case 

.     424 

Williams  v.  Field    .         .      163,  164,  171 

Williams  v.  Moor    . 

33,  4° 

Williams  v.  Steadman     . 

.     2gi 

Williams  v.  Williams 

161,  171 

Wilson  v.  Carnley  . 

•       55 

Wing  v.  Mill  . 

•       33 

Wiseman  v.  Vandeputt   . 

•     243 

Wood  v.  Hayes 

.     238 

Woodlife's  Case 

.     259 

Woodrop  Sims,  The 

266,  268 

Woodward  v.  Aston 

•       95 

Woodward  v.  Ro.ve 

161, 162 

Woolvil  v.  Young    . 

.     168 

Wright  v.  Reed 

.     191 

Wright  v.  Wilson    . 

•     423 

Yard  v.  Eland 
Yates  v.  Boen 
Young's  Case 


Zenobio  v.  Axtell 


13 

53 

436 


37i 


VOL.  VIII. 


LIST  OF  STATUTES 


52  Henry  III.  c.  23 

3  Edward  I.  c.  14  . 

4  ..  c.  14  . 
13  ..  st.  3  . 
15  Edward  III.  c.  5 
25           „  c.  17 

27  ,,  St.  2,  C. 

34  ..  c.  1 

17  Richard  II.  c.  8 
13  Henry  IV.  c.  7 

2  Henry  V.  c.  8 

3  Henry  VII.  c.  5 

c.  6 
n  „  c.  8 

19  „  c.  9 

c.  13 
32  Henry  VIII.  c.  9 
33 


c.  20 
c.  27 
c.  4 

C.   2 

c.  9 
c.  14 
c  5 
c.  20 


34,  35     .. 
35 
37 
1  Edward  VI 

3.  4 

5>6        >. 

1,  2  Philip  and  Mary  c 

1  Elizabeth  c.  16 

13  »         c-  2 

c.  7 
c.  8 

14  ..         c-  3 

c.  5 

23  ,.         c.  I 

39  ..         c.  3 

43  .,         c.  4 

,,  ,i         c-  I2 

1  James  I.  c.  15 

21         ,,        c.  12 

21         ,,        c.  16 

c.  19 

,»  :>  C.    24 

12  Charles  II.  c.  13 


13.  J4 
14 

22,  23 
29 
30 


c.  23 
c.  24 

C.  20 

c  3 

4 


1  William  and  Mary  c 


S3. 


18 


Sess.  2 


PAGE 

•  231 
.  269 
.  259 
.  231 
.  102 
.  231 
.  269 

•  331 

•  331 

•  331 

•  331 

103,  i°7 
.  103 
.  107 
.  231 

•  331 
398,  399 

•  439 
.  202 

•  236 
.  308 
.  108 

412,  417 

•  327 
109 

•  313 

•  327 

•  3  '4 
237-240 

109,  no 

•  324 

•  233 

•  324 

•  233 
412,  417 

.  286 

237-240 

.  no 

.   65 

237-240,  244 

.  231 

.  no 

.  290 

205,  237 

•  235 

•  65 

•  235 
405, 406, 410 

c  15  235 

xxxii 


PAGE 

3  William  and  Mary  c. 

') 

•     304 

4 

c. 

17 

•     203 

5-  6 

.1           c 

8 

•     235 

19                    »! 

11          c. 

20 

174. 

203,  205 

7,  8  William 

III.  C.    12    . 

.     235 

8,9 

II 

11 

c.  18  . 
c.  20  . 

.     244 
i88,  237 

II 

,, 

c.  32 

214, 

224,  225 

9 

» 

c.  26  . 
c.  2g   . 

.     210 
•     245 

,1 

,, 

c  35  • 

.     408 

g,  10 

„ 

c.  17  . 

•     171 

10 

,, 

c.  6 

.     2og 

3,  4  Anne 

c. 

9 

173.  174 

6 

c. 

3i      • 

•     469 

10           ,, 

c. 

14      . 

.     469 

12           ,, 

St 

.  2,  c.  16 

.     112 

1  George 

I. 

5t.  2,  C.  5      . 

320,  328 

6 

c.  18   . 

198 

215,  220 

31  George 

Ill 

•  c.  32 

.     412 

32 

c.  60 

•     345 

36 

c.  7 

3^>  32i 

53 

c.  160 

.     411 

57 

c.  6 

.     321 

1,  2  George 

IV.  c.  28 

.     210 

4 

c.  94 

.     221 

10             , 

c.  7 

.     412 

2,  3  Willi 

an 

L   IV.  C    115 

.     412 

3,  4 

IT 

c.  98 

.     191 

g,  10  Victoria  c.  59 

.     413 

11,  12       , 

C.    12 

•     321 

17,  18 

c.  90 
c.  104 

101,  112 
•     254 

23,  24       - 

c.  134 

•     4i3 

36,  37       . 

c.  66 

.     268 

38,  39       ,1 

c.  86 

•     392 

41,  42       , 

c.  13 

•     157 

45,  46      ,, 

c.  Gi       1. 

3. 

156, 

157,  163, 
igo 

51. 52       , 

c.  46 

.     416 

54.  55       - 

c.  51 

357 

56,  57       . 

c.  71 

52 

57.  58       , 

c.  60 

254 

63,  64 

c  51 

112 

6  Edward  VII.  c.  41 

284 

1,             ., 

c.  58 

482 

7 

c.  24 

.     196 

1,  2  George 

V.  c.  57 

26 

6,  268 

BOOK  IV  (Continued) 

(1485-1700) 

THE  COMMON  LAW  AND  ITS  RIVALS 


A  HISTORY  OF  ENGLISH  LAW 

PART  II 
THE   RULES   OF   LAW   {Continued) 

CHAPTER  III 

CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

THAT  the  essence  of  contract  is  agreement,  and  the  essence 
of  agreement  is  a  union  of  wills,  was  as  clearly  recognized 
by  the  lawyers  of  the  sixteenth  century  as  it  is  recog- 
nized by  us.  "  The  agreement  of  the  minds  of  the  parties,"  it 
was  said  in  1 5 53,1  "is  the  only  thing  the  law  respects  in 
contracts " ;  and  in  1 5  5 1  agreement  had  been  defined  as  the 
"  union,  collection,  copulation,  and  conjunction  of  two  or  more 
minds  in  anything  done  or  to  be  done."  2  Both  the  treatment  of 
contract  by  the  court  of  Chancery,  and  the  development  of  the 
action  of  assumpsit,  had  helped  the  lawyers  to  this  conclusion. 
We  have  seen  that  the  Chancellor,  starting  from  the  broad 
premise  that  redress  should  be  given  where  faith  was  broken,  had 
helped  to  familiarize  the  common  lawyers  with  the  idea  that 
an  agreement  as  such  ought  to  be  enforced ; 3  and  that  the 
common  lawyers  had  begun  to  give  technical  expression  to  this 
idea  by  the  developments  which  they  had  made  in  the  actions  of 
debt  and  assumpsit*  We  have  seen  that  the  developments  made 
in  both  these  actions  had  brought  this  idea  into  the  common  law; 
but  that  it  was  the  development  of  the  latter  action  which  was  the 
most  fruitful.  Debt  was  an  old  action  which  had  originated  at  a 
period  when  the  common  law  had  hardly  grasped  the  idea  that 
an  agreement  as  such  should  give  rise  to  an  action.  It  was 
essentially  proprietary  in  its  nature,5  and  therefore  it  was  not  so 
readily  adaptable  to  the  purpose  of  enforcing  agreements  as 
assumpsit,  in  which  the  element  of  agreement  had  had  from  the 
first  a  prominent  place.6 

1  Browning  v.  Beston,  Plowden  at  pp.  140-141. 

2  Reniger  v.  Fogossa,  Plowden  at  p.  17. 

3  Vol.  v  295-297.  *  Vol.  iii  420-423,  429-453, 
s  Vol.  ii  368 ;  vol.  iii  420.  '  Ibid  429^430,  442. 

VOL.   VIII.— I  I 


2         CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

This  development  of  the  idea  of  an  enforceable  agreement, 
naturally  brought  to  the  front  the  problem  of  distinguishing  the 
agreements  which  the  law  would  enforce,  from  those  which  it  would 
not — of  drawing  the  line  between  contracts  and  mere  pacts.  It 
was  a  problem  which  confronted  both  the  court  of  Chancery  and 
the  common  law  courts.  Both  sets  of  courts  contributed  some- 
thing to  its  solution  ;  and  ideas  derived  from  both  can  be  traced 
in  the  history  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration  which  solved  it  But 
we  shall  see  that  the  main  essentials  and  ultimate  contents  of  that 
doctrine  are  wholly  derived  from  the  rules  which  regulated  the 
competence  of  the  common  law  actions  of  debt  and  assumpsit,  and 
more  especially  from  the  rules  developed  by  the  successive  expan- 
sions of  the  latter  action.  In  the  first  place,  therefore,  I  shall 
trace  the  history  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration. 

Naturally  the  recognition  and  growth  of  the  actionable  agree- 
ment, and  the  settlement  of  the  limits  within  which  such  agree- 
ments were  actionable,  gave  rise  to  the  development  of  other  rules 
of  contract  law.  Thus,  the  law  began  to  acquire  some  rules  as 
to  the  causes  and  effects  of  the  invalidity  of  contracts,  as  to  the 
manner  of  their  enforcement,  and  as  to  their  discharge.  In  the 
second  place,  therefore,  I  shall  say  something  as  to  the  origins 
of  some  of  the  modern  rules  on  these  topics,  which  begin  to  make 
their  appearance  during  this  period. 

Lastly,  it  will  be  necessary  to  say  something  of  the  origins  of 
our  modern  law  as  to  quasi-contract.  We  have  seen  that  it  was  at 
the  end  of  this  period  that  the  action  of  assumpsit  was  being 
extended  to  enforce  some  of  those  quasi-contractual  relations, 
which  were  enforceable  by  the  action  of  debt.1  We  shall  see  that 
it  was  the  adaptation  of  the  action  of  assumpsit  to  this  new  use, 
and  the  development  of  its  competence  in  this  new  sphere,  which 
have  created  our  modern  law  of  quasi-contract. 

My  arrangement  of  this  chapter  will  therefore  be  as  follows  : — 
§  i  the  Doctrine  of  Consideration ;  §  2  the  Invalidity,  Enforce- 
ment, and  Discharge  of  Contracts  ;   §  3  Quasi-contract. 

§  1.    The  Doctrine  of  Consideration 

In  the  first  place,  I  shall  say  something  of  the  term  considera- 
tion. We  shall  see  that  the  history  of  the  term,  and  of  the  manner 
in  which  it  gradually  came  to  be  a  word  with  different  technical 
meanings  in  the  spheres  of  the  equitable  and  common  law  jurisdic- 
tions, tells  us  something  of  the  place  which  it  acquired  in  the  law 
of  contract,  and  of  some  of  the  characteristic  features  which  it  there 
developed.  In  the  second  place,  I  shall  give  some  account  of  the 
development  of  the  doctrine  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 

1  Vol.  iii  450-451 ;  vol.  vi  639. 


THE  TERM  CONSIDERATION  3 

centuries.  Some  of  the  rules  then  developed  have  become  the 
settled  rules  of  the  modern  common  law  ;  but  they  have  not  attained 
this  position  without  difficulty.  We  shall  see  that,  though  the  chief 
and  most  permanent  elements  in  the  modern  doctrine  of  considera- 
tion have  sprung  from  the  procedural  requirements  of  the  action  of 
assumpsit,  many  difficulties  have  arisen  in  the  process  of  translat- 
ing these  procedural  rules  into  the  substantive  rules  of  the  modern 
law.  These  difficulties  have  arisen  partly  from  the  fact  that 
the  action  of  assumpsit  was  constantly  expanding  all  through  this 
period  ;  but  chiefly  from  the  fact  that  other  elements,  derived  from 
other  sources,  have  made  their  influence  felt  We  shall  see  that 
we  must  reckon  with  influences  derived  from  the  action  of  debt, 
with  the  influence  of  the  idea  of  consideration  which  was  being 
developed  by  the  court  of  Chancery,  and,  later,  with  the  influence 
of  continental  systems  of  law  which  came  through  the  law  merchant 
Some  of  these  influences  helped  to  introduce  into  the  doctrine  of 
consideration  an  element  of  moral  obligation,  which  threatened  at 
one  time  to  reduce  it  to  a  position  of  merely  evidential  value ;  and, 
long  after  this  idea  had  been  got  rid  of,  they  exercised  a  disturbing 
influence  on  its  evolutioa  It  was  not  till  this  disturbing  influence 
was  removed  by  the  decisions  of  the  last  three-quarters  of  the  nine- 
teenth century,  that  the  doctrine  has  been  settled  mainly  on  the  basis 
of  those  ideas  derived  from  the  action  of  assumpsit  from  which  it 
started  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  With  these 
two  topics,  therefore,  its  development  in  the  eighteenth  and  early 
nineteenth  centuries,  and  its  settlement  in  the  last  three-quarters 
of  the  nineteenth  century,  I  shall  deal  next.  Lastly,  i  shall 
endeavour  to  estimate  briefly  the  comparative  merits  of  the  English 
doctrine  of  consideration  and  the  modern  continental  developments 
of  the  Roman  causa. 

The  Term_  Consideration 

We  have  seen  that  the  one  idea  which  the  early  common  law 
borrowed  from  the  Roman  law,  was  the  idea  that  the  nude  pact 
was  not  enforceable1  This  idea  was  adapted  to  the  common  law 
of  the  thirteenth  century,  and  took  shape  in  the  principle  that  only 
those  agreements  were  actionable  which  could  be  brought  within 
the  competence  of  some  one  of  the  older  personal  actions.2  But,  as 
soon  as  the  older  personal  actions  began  to  be  employed  for  the 
purpose  of  enforcing  certain  kinds  of  agreements,  it  began  to  be 
obvious  that  some  word  or  expression  was  needed  to  differentiate 
the  agreements  which  could  "be  enforced  by  them,  from  the  agree- 
ments which  could  riot  It  was  in  connection  with  the  action 
of  debt  that  this  need  was  then  chiefly  felt,  for  the  requirement  of 

1  Vol.  iii  413.  *  For  these  actions  see  voL  iii  414-428. 


4         CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

a  sealed  writing  as  a  condition  precedent  for  bringing  the  action  of 
covenant  supplied  a  clear  test  of  enforceability.  But  we  have  seen 
that  debt  did  not  lie  unless  the  plaintiff  had  given  something  for 
the  promise ;  and  the  expressions  used  to  signify  that  the  plaintiff 
had  satisfied  this  requirement  were  at  first  general  words,  such  as 
"cause"  or  "occasion,"  since  the  benefit  received  was  generally 
the  motive  or  reason  for  making  a  grant.1  We  have  seen,  how- 
ever, that  in  the  fifteenth  century,  the  more  precise  expression 
"quid  pro  quo"  had  been  appropriated  to  express  the  conditions 
under  which  the  action  of  debt  would  lie  ;  and  that,  in  consequence, 
it  had  began  to  acquire  almost  a  technical  meaning.2  But,  because 
the  expression  "  quid  pro  quo "  had  thus  acquired  a  technical 
meaning,  some  more  general  word  was  needed  to  express  the  act 
or  other  circumstances  which  had  led  up  to  or  was  the  motive  or 
reason  for  a  given  transaction.  It  is  clear  from  the  Year  Books  of 
the  fifteenth  and  early  sixteenth  century  that  the  word  "  considera- 
tion "  was  used  for  this  purpose ;  and  the  way  in  which  it  was 
used  shows  that  it  had  not  then  acquired  a  technical  meaning.3 
But,  as  soon  as  the  action  of  assumpsit  began  to  expand, 
so  as  to  remedy  nonfeasances  in  breach  of  agreements,  on  the 
faith  of  which  the  plaintiff  had  incurred  some  charge,  the  need  for 
some  compendious  word  to  express  the  incurring  of  this  charge, 
which  rendered  the  agreement  actionable,  began  to  be  very  strongly 
felt.  The  expression  "quid  pro  quo"  was  clumsy  and  had  been 
appropriated  to  the  action  of  debt4  On  the  other  hand,  the 
expression  "  considej^tioji^jwaLs_^jmore^  convenient  wordt^both 
because  it  had  a  far  more  general  significance,  and  because,  within 
thejphere  of  the  comm^Ja^jurisdiction7"it  had  not  yet  fjgcome 
a  technical  term. 

~~WhTle  these  developments  were  taking  place  in  the  sphere  of 
the  jurisdiction  of  the  common  law  courts,  the  court  of  Chancery 
had  been  obliged  to  tackle  a  somewhat  similar  problem.  We 
have  seen  that,  for  the  purpose  of  its  jurisdiction  both  over  con- 
tract and  over  uses,  it  had  become  necessary  to  lay  down  conditions 
as  to  the  circumstances  under  which  it  would  act.  It  had  become 
necessary  to  distinguish  between  the  enforceable  and  the  unenforce- 
able agreement,5  and  between  cases  in  which  it  would  and  cases  in 

1  "  Par  lescrit  qil  mest  avant  il  suppose  qe  il  nous  faira  certein  services  les  queux 
sont  la  cause  de  sa  demande,"  Y.B.  6,  7  Ed.  II.  (S.S.)  83  per  Westcot  arg. ;  "  Dont 
del  hure  que  ceste  annuite  fu  grante  issint  pur  les  services  issint  les  services  sont 
loccasion,"  Y.B.  5  Ed.  II.  (S.S.)  (1312)  2  per  Herle  arg.  2  Vol.  iii  421-423. 

8  An  instance  of  the  untechnical  use  of  the  word  at  common  law  will  be  found  in 
Y.B.  12  Ed.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  2  per  Choke,  "  s'il  dit  que  un  estranger  baile  les  biens  a  luy 
sans  ceo  que  le  pleintiff  bailie,  ce  n'est  purpose,  car  icy  n'est  nul  consideration,  per 
que  il  duist  traverser  le  contrary  "  ;  and  Y.B.  20  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  20,  "  bargaine  ou 
autre  consideration." 

*  "  The  term  quid  pro  quo  was  exceedingly  awkward,  and  besides,  usage  had 
associated  this  term  exclusively  with  debt,"  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability 
ii  37.  5Vol.  v  294-295. 


THE  TERM  CONSIDERATION  5 

which  it  would  not  protect  a  cestui  que  use.1  We  have  seen  that 
in  the  case  of  contract  it  adopted  the  canonist  theory  of  causa, 
and  that  the  English  word  which  it  used  to  express  this  conception 
was  consideration.2  This  use  of  the  word  tended  to  give  the  term, 
if  not  a  more  technical,  at  any  rate  a  more  precise  meaning. 
Possibly  it  might  have  acquired  the  same  technical  meaning  as  the 
canonists  had  given  to  the  word  "causa,"  if  the  court  of  Chancery 
had  been  able  to  gain  control  over  the  development  of  the  law  of 
contract.  But  we  have  seen  that  the  common  law  rejected  so 
wide  a  test  of  the  enforceability  of  contracts;  and  that  the  theory 
of  contract,  evolved  in  the  sphere  of  common  law  jurisdiction, 
became  the  theory7  of  English  law.3  Hence  a  doctrine  of  con- 
sideration in  this  form  failed  to  get  a  foothold  in  English  law ; 
and  this  use  of  thejterm  " consideration"  disappeared  with^fche 
disappearance  of  the  theory  of  contract,  which  had  begun  to  be 
worked  out  by  the  mediaeval  chancellors.  On  the  other  hand, 
tHe  use  of  the  term  in  connection  with  usgs  did  get  a  permanent 
foothold  in  English  law.  We  have  seen  that  in  that  connection  it 
was  used  to  express  the  conditions  under  which  equity  would 
imply  a  use ;  and  that,  in  the  course  of  the  sixteenth  century,  those 
conditions  had  come  to  be  either  the  creation  of  a  tenure,4  the 
payment  of  money,5  or  love  and  natural  affection.6  We  have  seen 
that  the  first  kind  of  consideration  soon  ceased  to  be  important7 
But  the  two  last,  termed  respectively  "valuable"  and  "good." 
consideration,  came  to  be  technical  terms  of  permanent  importance 
in  the  law  of  conveyancing.8  We  shall  see  that  this  use  of  the 
term  by  equity  has  had  an  appreciable,  though  an  indirect 
influence,  upon  certain  phases  in  the  later  history  of  the  doctrine 
of  consideration  developed  by  the  common  law  courts.9 

Thus,  in  the  earlier  half  of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  word 
consideration,  when  used  in  connection  with  the  law  of  contract, 
had  not  acquired  a  technical  meaning  either  at  law  or  in  equity. 
It  was  no  doubt  frequently  used  ;  but  other  words  and  expressions 
were  often  used  in  competition  with  it  to  express  the  same  idea. 
Thus,  as  Mr.  Street  points  out,10  St.  Germain  in  the  Doctor  and 
Student  uses  the  following  expressions :  "  Recompence  (four 
times),  cause  (three  times),  a  certain  consideration  (twice),  con- 
sideration of  worldly  profit  (once),  cause  in  the  sense  of  a  desire  to 
maintain  the  cause  of  learning  or  service  of  God  (once),  quid  pro 
quo  (once),  goods  or  some  other  profit  (once),  thing  assigned  for  a 

1  Vol.  iv  424,  425-427.  a  Vol.  v  294-295  ;  L.Q.R.  xxiv  382. 

3  Vol.  v  296.  *  Vol.  iv  429.  s  Ibid  424.  « Ibid  425-426. 

*  For  the  history  and  influence  of  the  idea  that  the  creation  of  a  tenure  is  a 
consideration,  see  ibid  429-430,  469-470. 

8  Ibid  427  ;  above  vol.  vii  359.  •  Below  12-13,  26-29,  31-32,  36-38. 

10  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  39  n.  1. 


s 


6        CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

promise  (once),  new  charge  (once),  charge  by  reason  of  the 
promise  (once)."  The  Termes  de  la  Ley1  defines  it  as  the  material 
cause  or  quid  pro  quo  of  a  contract,  without  which  it  will  not  be 
effectual  or  binding — thus  explaining  the  use  in  the  law  of  contract 
of  the,  as  yet,  less  technical  word  "  consideration,"  by  reference  to 
the  more  technical  expression  "  quid  pro  quo."  Similarly  in  1 566, 
in  the  case  of  Sharington  v.  Strotton?  which,  as  we  have  seen,  was  a 
case  which  turned  upon  the  sufficiency  of  love  and  natural  affection 
to  raise  a  use,3  it  is  clear  that,  in  relation  to  the  law  of  contract, 
the  term  is  used  in  a  semi-popular  sense  to  mean  the  circumstances 
which  will  make  the  contract  enforceable,  either  by  the  action  of 
debt  or  by  the  action  of  assumpsit;4  in  Calthorpes  Case  (1  574)j5 
it  is  used  in  quite  a  general  way  to  mean  "a  cause  or  meritorious 
occasion  requiring  a  mutual  recompence  in  fact  or  in  law " ;  ' 
various  illustrations  are  given  of  the  need  for  a  consideration  in 
this  wide  sense  in  the  law  of  property ;  and  in  contract  the  need 
for  it  is  illustrated  by  a  reference  to  the  quid  pro  quo.7 

We  have  seen  that  it  was  during  the  latter  half  of  the  sixteenth 
century  that  assumpsit  became  alternative  to  debt,  when  debt  was 
brought  on  a  contract,  and  that  it  became  a  remedy  on  purely 
executory  contracts.8  gy  the_end  of  jhe_century,  therefore,  it  had 
become  definitely  the  chief  contractual  action  of_the  common  law. 
Bur7  durihg^thelatter  part  of  that  century,  the  pleaders  were 
beginning  to  use  the  word  "  consideration  "  to  introduce  the  facts 
upon~~wnich  they^eliecTlo  make  the  promi^_enforceab]e_by 
ajssjimp_sit.9     Hence  it  is  not  surprisingToHn3  that  the  word  then 

1  Cited  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  39  n.  g. 

2  Plowden  300.  3  Vol.  iv  426. 

4  "  For  if  upon  consideration  that  you  are  my  familiar  friend  or  acquaintance,  or 
my  brother,  I  promise  to  pay  you  ^,20,  at  such  a  day,  you  shall  not  have  an  action 
upon  the  case  or  an  action  of  debt  lor  it,  for  it  is  but  a  nude  and  barren  contract,  et 
ex  undo  pacto  non  oritur  actio,  and  there  is  no  sufficient  cause  for  the  payment,  nor  is 
anything  done  or  given  on  the  one  part,  for  you  were  my  brother  or  my  acquaintance 
before,  and  so  will  you  be  afterwards  ;  so  that  nothing  is  newly  done  on  the  one  part, 
as  is  requisite  in  contracts,  and  also  in  covenants  upon  consideration,"  Plowden  at 
p.  302. 

8  Dyer  334b.  6  At  f.  336b. 

7  "  Contracts  and  bargains  have  a  quid  pro  quo,"  ibid.  8  Vol.  iii  441-446. 

9Joscelin  v.  Shelton  (1557)  3  Leo.  4,  where  ''  the  plaintiff  declared  that  the 
defendant,  in  consideration  that  the  son  of  the  plaintiff  would  marry  the  daughter  of 
the  defendant,  assumed  and  promi.-ed  to  pay  to  him  etc.,"  is  perhaps  the  earliest 
instance  of  the  use  of  the  term  in  this  sense;  Ames,  Lectures  147  n.  1,  cites  this  case, 
and  says  that  "it  is  a  noteworthy  fact  that  in  the  reports  of  the  half  dozen  cases  of 
the  reigns  of  Henry  VIII.  and  Edward  VI.  the  word  'consideration'  does  not  ap- 
pear "  ;  the  fact  that  in  Whorwood  v.  Gybbons  (1587)  Golds.  48  it  was  said  that  "  it 
is  a  common  course  in  actions  upon  the  case  against  him  by  whom  the  debt  is  due, 
to  declare  without  any  words  in  considcratione,"  testifies  at  once  to  the  growing  habit 
of  using  these  words,  and  to  the  fact  that  the  us  ige  was  not  quite  settled ;  it  was 
fairly  well  settled  by  1585,  for  Periam,  J.,  in  Sidenham  and  Worlington's  Case  2  Leo. 
at  p.  225  said,  "in  an  action  upon  the  case  upon  a  promise,  the  declaration  is  laid, 
that  the  defendant  for  and  in  consideration  of  £20. to  him  paid,  (postea  scil.)  that  is  to 
say,  at  a  day  after,  super  se  assumpsit." 


THE  TERM  CONSIDERATION  7 

acquired  the  technical  meaning  of  the  facts  or  circumstances  which 
must  be  proved  in  order  to  make  a  promise  enforceable  by  this 
action.  This  fact  is  clearly  illustrated  by  chief  baron  Manwood's 
answer  to  a  writ  of  error  in  a  case  to  which  he  was  a  party.1  Not 
only  does  he,  throughout  his  answer,  use  the  word  consideration 
in  this  sense,  but  he  also  classifies  the  various  possible  considera- 
tions as  follows:  "There  are,"  he  says,  'three  manner  of  con- 
siderations upon  which  an  assumpsit  may  be  grounded  :  (i)  a  debt 
precedent ;  (2)  when  he  to  whom  such  a  promise  is  made  is 
damnified  by  doing  anything,  or  spends  his  labour  at  the  instance 
of  the  promiser,  although  no  benefit  cometh  to  the  promiser  .  .  . 
(3)  or  there  is  a  present  consideration."2  It  is  clear  that  the 
second  of  these  considerations  originates  in  the  extension  of  the 
action  of  assumpsit  to  cover  certain  kinds  of  nonfeasance  in 
breach  of  an  undertaking  ; 3  that  the  first  originates  in  the  extension 
of  the  action  to  enforce  a  promise  to  pay  an  existing  debt 
(indebitatus  assumpsit) ; 4  and  that  the  third  originates  in  the 
extension  of  the  action  to  enforce  a  promise  which  is  given  in 
return  for  a  promise 5 

Consideration  thus  acquired  its  technical  meaning  in  the 
common  law  mainly  in  relation  to  the  action  of  assumpsit.  It 
became  the  compendious  word  used  to  express  the  conditions 
under  which  that  action  would  lie,  and  therefore  the  condition 
precedent  for  the  validity  of  all  those  contracts  which  could  only 
be  enforced  by  that  action.  Hence,  as  we  shall  see,  the  leading 
characteristics  of  consideration,  which  emerged  in  the  sixteenth 
and  seventeenth  centuries,  originate  in  the  rules  for  the  competence 
of  this  action.  But  we  have  seen  that  the  lawyers,  in  extending 
the  action  of  assumpsit  to  cover  the  field  of  simple  contracts,  used 
analogies  taken  from  the  action  of  debt ; 6  and  that  they  were 
fully  aware  of  the  analogy  existing  between  the  quid  pro  quo 
which  the  plaintiff  must  prove  in  order  to  succeed  in  an  action  of 
debt,  and  the  consideration  which  he  must  prove  in  order  to  suc- 
ceed in  an  action  of  assumpsit.7  It  is  not  surprising,  therefore, 
that  ideas  derived  from  the  quid  pro  quo  should  have  had  some 
permanent  influence  on  the  development  of  the  law  of  contract, 
and  that  its  influence  should  still  be  apparent,  not  only  in  the 
sixteenth  century 8  but  also  in  the  definition  of  consideration 
accepted  in  our  modern  law.9  Similarly,  we  have  seen  that  the 
term  consideration  had  developed  a  different  technical  meaning  in 
equity.10     As  the  relations  between  the  court  of  Chancery  and  the 

1  Manwood  and  Burston's  Case  (1587)  2  Leo.  203.  2  Ibid  at  p.  204. 

3  Vol.  iii  434-441.  4  Ibid  442-444.  5  Ibid  444-446. 

6  Ibid  436-438,  445-446.  7  Ibid  440.  8  Below  10-11,  22,  24. 

v  Below  io-ii.  10  Vol.  iv  424,  425-426 ;  above  4-5. 


8         CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

common  law  courts  were  close,  it  is  not  surprising  that  the  mean- 
ing attached  to  the  term  in  equity  should  have  influenced  indirectly 
the  meaning  attached  to  it  by  the  courts  of  common  law.1  The 
result  is  that,  though  the  main  principles  of  the  doctrine  of  con- 
sideration have  been  developed  as  logical  deductions  from  the 
conditions  for  success  in  the  action  of  assumpsit,  other  influences 
have  made  themselves  felt ;  and  in  the  eighteenth  and  early  nine- 
teenth centuries,  some  of  them  seemed  likely  to  give  the  doctrine 
a  shape  very  different  from  the  shape  which  it  was  taking  in  the 
sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  when  it  was  being  developed 
mainly  from  its  procedural  basis  in  assumpsit.2  During  the 
nineteenth  century  a  return  was  made  to  this  procedural  basis.3 
But  the  result  has  been  that  the  final  shape  of  the  doctrine  has  not 
been  settled  till  quite  modern  times. 

To  the  history  of  this  settlement  we  must  now  turn ;  and 
firstly  we  must  consider  some  of  the  leading  characteristics  of  the 
doctrine  which  emerged  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries. 

Consideration  in  the  Sixteenth  and  Seventeenth  Centuries 

The  main  influence  which  shaped  the  development  of  the 
doctrine  during  this  period  must  be  sought  in  the  nature  and 
competence  of  "express"  or  "special"  assumpsit.4  But  other 
influences,  which  came  partly  from  the  actions  of  debt  and  account, 
and  the  action  of  indebitatus  assumpsit,  which,  during  this  period, 
was  superseding  them,5  and  partly  from  the  equitable  treatment 
of  consideration ;  tended  to  modify,  and  even  sometimes  to  con- 
tradict, the  principles  which  flowed  logically  from  the  nature  and 
competence  of  "  express  "  or  "  special "  assumpsit.  The  result  was 
that,  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  principles  under- 
lying the  doctrine  were  on  many  points  obscure  and  confused. 
Ideas  which  originated  from  these  diverse  sources  had  led  to 
contradictory  decisions  on  very  similar  sets  of  facts ;  and  though 
certain  principles,  originating  from  the  procedural  basis  of  special 
assumpsit,  seemed  to  be  firmly  grasped,  the  competing  influences 
had  sometimes  given  rise  to  decisions  which  cast  doubts,  or  im- 
posed limitations  even  on  these  principles. 

Obviously  it  is  difficult  to  give  a  clear  account  of  the  genesis 
of  a  doctrine  which  began  its  career  amid  these  conflicting  in- 
fluences. I  think  that  it  will  be  best  understood  if  I  take  certain 
of  the  principles,  which  were  obviously  derived  from  the  conditions 

1  Below  12-13,  26-29,  31-32,  36-38.  2  Below  25  seqq.  3  Below  34  seqq. 

4  For  the  difference  between  "  special  "  assumpsit  brought  on  a  contract,  and  in- 
debitatus assumpsit  brought  on  a  debt  formerly  only  enforceable  by  action  of  debt,  see 
vol.  iii  446. 

6  Ibid  420-423,  426-428,  442-444. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES        9 

under  which  special  assumpsit  or  indebitatus  assumpsit  lay,  and 
then  consider  in  each  case  whether,  and  to  what  extent,  they  were 
modified  by  other  competing  influences.  The  principles  which  I 
propose  to  treat  upon  these  lines  are  the  following:  (i)  Consider- 
ation may  consist  in  mutual  promises,  a  precedent  debt,  or  a 
detriment  to  the  promisee.  (2)  Consideration  need  not  move  to 
the  promisor,  but  it  must  move  from  the  promisee.  (3)  Consider- 
ation may  be  executory  or  executed,  but  it  cannot  be  past.  (4) 
Consideration  need  not  be  adequate,  but  it  must  be  certain. 
(5)  Consideration  must  be  an  act  or  forbearance  of  some  value  in 
the  eye  of  the  law. 

(1)  Consideration  may  consist  in  mutual  promises \  a  precedent 
debt,  or  a  detriment  to  the  promisee. 

We  have  seen  that  it  was  settled,  during  the  latter  part  of  the 
sixteenth  century,  that  mutual  promises,  provided  that  they  were 
made  at  the  same  instant,  were  consideration  for  each  other.1  It 
was  only  through  the  action  of  assumpsit  that  wholly  executory 
contracts  of  this  kind  could  be  enforced.  Therefore  the  rule  thus 
ascertained  for  the  competence  of  assumpsit  could  not  be  affected 
by  rules  derived  from  any  other  source.  From  the  end  of  the 
sixteenth  century  it  has  been  accepted  without  question  or  doubt, 
and  for  that  reason  it  has  no  history. 

We  have  seen  that  it  was  settled  in  Slade's  Case  that  a  pre- 
cedent debt  was  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise,  express 
or  implied,  to  pay  it ;  -  and  we  shall  see  that  this  rule  has  made  it 
possible  to  sue  in  indebitatus  assumpsit  on  obligations  of  a  quasi- 
contractual  nature.3  But  it  is  clear  that  this  kind  of  consideration 
is  diffiult  to  reconcile  with  the  undoubted  rule  that  a  consideration 
cannot  be  past  This  objection  was  raised  in  1 6 1 7 *  to  an 
assumpsit  on  an  express  promise  to  pay  a  precedent  debt  for  goods 
delivered ;  but  it  was  overruled  on  the  ground  that,  as  the  debt 
always  continued,  the  consideration  was  not  past5  But  obviously, 
as  the  delivery  of  the  goods,  which  constituted  the  debt,  was  a 
past  act  done  without  any  reference  to  the  express  subsequent 
promise,  it  was  not  comparable,  as  Haughton,  J.,  apparently  tried 
to  argue,'  to  an  executed  consideration.  It  was  in  fact  a  past 
consideration ;  but,  in  spite  of  this  fact,  it  was  well  settled  that 
assumpsit  lay.     We  shall  see  that  this  rule  that  a  precedent  debt 

1  Vol.  iii  445.  3  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep.  92b  ;  vol.  iii  444. 

3  Below  88  seqq.  4  Hodge  v.  Vavisour  3  Bulstr.  222. 

5  "  The  debt  here  always  continues,"  per  Dodderidge,  J.,  at  p.  223. 

•  "  In  consideration  that  the  plaintiff  hath  built  a  house  for  the  defendant,  he  did 
assume  and  promise  to  pay  him  so  much,  this  is  executed,  here  the  assumpsit  is  for 
money,  this  is  to  be  paid  on  request ;  here  the  defendant  is  clogged  with  a  debt  con- 
tinually, and  therefore  this  is  here  a  good  consideration  to  raise  a  promise." 


10      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

was  a  valid  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise,  had  a  large 
effect  upon  the  growth  of  the  doctrine,  by  helping  to  introduce  the 
notion  that  the  presence  of  a  moral  obligation  might  be  sufficient 
to  constitute  a  consideration.1  We  shall  see,  too,  that  this  notion 
tended  to  obscure  the  law  as  to  the  difference  between  a  past  and 
an  executed  consideration,  and  to  introduce  doubts  and  difficulties 
as  to  the  validity  of  a  past  consideration.2 

That  consideration  could  consist  merely  in  a  detriment  to  the 
promisee  was  clearly  recognized  in  the  Doctor  and  Student,3  and 
in  many  cases  decided  at  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  and  the  begin- 
ning of  the  seventeenth  centuries.4  One  instance  will  suffice.  In 
William  Banes  Case5  (1612),  where  an  executrix,  in  considera- 
tion of  forbearance,  promised  to  pay  the  debt  of  her  testator,  it 
was  held  that  the  consideration  was  good ;  "for  it  is  as  much  as  if 
a  stranger  had  said  to  the  plaintiff  forbear  your  debt,  and  do  not 
sue  the  defendant  till  Michaelmas,  and  at  the  said  feast  I  will  pay 
you  your  debt,  that  is  a  good  consideration,  although  it  cannot  be 
any  benefit  to  him  who  makes  the  promise  ;  yet  because  it  is  a 
damage  to  the  creditor  to  forbear  his  suit  or  duty,  it  is  a  good 
consideration."  6  This  is  clearly  the  direct  result  of  the  fact  that 
assumpsit  was  originally  an  action  in  tort  ;  for  it  followed  that 
the  gist  of  the  action  was,  not  the  benefit  got  by  the  defendant- 
promisor,  but  the  detriment  incurred  by  the  plaintiff-promisee  on 
the  faith  of  the  defendant's  promise.  But  in  many,  perhaps  in 
most  cases,  the  detriment  incurred  by  the  promisee  is  also  a  benefit 
to  the  promisor ;  for  this  is  always  the  case  when  the  detriment 
consists  in  a  payment,  conveyance  of  property,  or  service  rendered 
to  the  promisor.  In  the  action  of  debt  the  lawyers  naturally 
regarded  the  matter  from  the  side  of  benefit,  and  asked  whether 
the  promisor  had  received  a  quid  pro  quo.  But  we  have  seen  that, 
when  consideration  was  as  yet  an  untechnical  word,  it  was  some- 
times used  synonymously  with  quid  pro  quo.7  Thus  it  is  not 
surprising  to  find  that  Coke  said  that  "  every  consideration  that 
doth  charge  the  defendant  in  an  assumpsit  must  be  to  the  benefit 
of  the  defendant  or  charge  of  the  plaintiff";8  and  that  the 
accepted  definition  of  consideration  is  that  it  consists  in  "  some 
right,  interest,  profit,  or  benefit  accruing  to  the  one  party,  or  some 
forbearance,  detriment,  loss,  or   responsibility  given    suffered    or 

1  Below  25-26.  2  Below  15-17.  3  Vol.  Hi  440-441. 

4  See  Richard's  and  Bartlet's  Case  (1584)  1  Leo.  19,  cited  below  21  ;  Greenleaf  v. 
Barker  (1591)  Cro.  Eliza,  at  p.  194 ;  Knight  v.  Rushworth  (1596)  ibid  at  p.  470  ; 
and  see  the  other  cases  cited  by  Ames,  Lectures  143  n.  3. 

6  9  Co.  Rep.  f.  93b.  6  At  f.  94a.  7  Above  5-6. 

8  Stone  v.  Wythipol  (1588)  Cro.  Eliza,  at  p.  126  ;  so  also  in  Greenleaf  v.  Barker 
(1591)  ibid  at  p.  194,  Gawdy  and  Fenner,  JJ.,  said,  "  every  consideration  must  be  for 
the  benefit  of  the  defendant,  or  some  other  at  his  request,  or  a  thing  done  by  the 
plaintiff,  for  which  he  laboureth  or  hath  prejudice." 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       11 

undertaken  by  the  other."  1  In  truth,  detriment  to  the  promisee 
is  of  the  essence  of  the  doctrine,  and  benefit  to  the  promisor  is, 
when  it  exists,  merely  an  accident.2  The  idea  that  benefit  to  the 
promisor  is  as  much  of  its  essence  as  detriment  to  the  promisee,  is, 
as  it  has  been  truly  said,  "  a  heritage  from  debt."  3  In  fact  it  comes 
from  a  period  when  analogies  taken  from  the  action  of  debt  were 
used  to  explain  the  extensions  made  in  the  sphere  of  the  action 
of  assumpsit,  and  when  the  doctrine  of  consideration  was  in  its 
infancy  ;  but  it  has  lasted  long,  and  has  had  in  consequence  some 
influence  on  the  evolution  of  the  doctrine.  That  it  is  erroneous 
and  that  it  has  been  influential  we  shall  see  more  clearly  in  the 
following  paragraphs. 

(2)  Consideration  need  not  move  to  the  promisor,  but  it  must  move 
from  the  promisee. 

The  essence  of  consideration  is  thus,  not  a  benefit  to  the 
promisor-defendant,  but  a  detriment  to  the  promisee-plaintiff. 
That  detriment  may,  it  is  true,  have  resulted  in  a  benefit  to  the 
defendant ;  but  this  fact — if  fact  it  be — is,  as  we  have  seen,  wholly 
immaterial.  But  though  the  detriment  to  the  plaintiff  need  not 
have  resulted  in  any  benefit  to  the  defendant,  the  form  of  the 
action  made  it  necessary  that  the  detriment,  incurred  on  the  faith  of 
the  promise,  should  have  been  incurred  by  the  plaintiff  to  whom  the 
promise  was  made ;  for  it  is  he  alone  to  whom  the  promise  has  been 
made,  on  the  faith  of  which  he  has  suffered  a  detriment  by  altering 
his  position.  This  principle  was  recognized  in  the  seventeenth 
century.  In  1646  it  was  held  that,  where  J.  and  B.  contracted 
with  each  other  that  each  should  pay  a  sum  of  money  to  their 
children  who  had  intermarried,  the  administrator  of  B.  could  sue 
J.  for  his  contribution,  "though  he  should  receive  no  benefit  if  he 
did  recover"  ;4  and  in  1668,  in  the  case  of  Bourne  v.  Mason,5  a 
plaintiff  was  non-suited  because  "he  did  nothing  of  trouble  to 
himself  or  benefit  to  the  defendant,  but  is  a  meer  stranger  to  the 
consideration." 

This  principle  seems  to  us  to  be  almost  too  plain  for  argument — 
on  historical  grounds  because  it  is  an  obvious  deduction  from  the 

1  Currie  v.  Missa  (1875)  L.R.  10  Ex.  at  p.  162  ;  similarly  Martin,  B.,  in  Scotson  v. 
Pegg  (1861)  6  H.  and  N.  at  p.  299  said  that  "  any  act  done  whereby  the  contracting 
party  receives  a  benefit  is  a  good  consideration  for  a  promise  by  him,"  and  Wilde,  B.'s 
judgment,  ibid  at  p.  300,  is  partially  based  on  the  same  view  of  consideration ;  see 
below  41. 

2  This  was  for  the  first  time  pointed  out  by  Langdell,  Contracts  §  64. 

3  Street,  op.  clt.  ii  68 ;  as  Langdell,  op.  cit.  §  64,  says,  "  one  of  the  most  striking 
differences  between  debt  and  assumpsit  in  respect  to  consideration  is,  that  in  debt  the 
consideration  must  inure  to  the  benefit  of  the  debtor,  while  in  assumpsit  it  may  inure 
to  the  benefit  of  the  promisor,  or  of  some  third  person,  or  to  the  benefit  of  no  one." 

4  Anon.  Style  6.  5  1  Ventris  6. 


12      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

conditions  under  which  assumpsit  lay,  and  on  logical  grounds 
because  it  is  an  elementary  principle  of  contract  law  that  only  the 
parties  to  the  contract  can  be  bound  by  or  take  benefits  under  a 
contract.  But  it  was  by  no  means  firmly  grasped  at  this  period. 
This  was  due  mainly  to  three  causes. 

(i)  The  disturbing  influence  of  the  equitable  conception  of 
consideration. 

We  shall  see  that  in  the  sixteenth  century  it  was  distinctly 
asserted  that,  though  love  and  natural  affection  were  sufficient 
considerations  to  raise  a  use,  they  would  not  support  an  assumpsit.1 
But  in  Bourne  v.  Mason  earlier  cases,  which  were  influenced  by 
this  conception,  were  approved.  In  the  first  of  these  cases  it  was 
held  that  a  son  could  sue  on  a  promise  made  to  his  father  to  settle 
land  on  his  marriage ;  and  in  the  second  it  was  held  that  the 
daughter  of  a  physician  could  sue  on  a  promise,  made  to  her 
father,  to  give  her  a  sum  of  money  if  he  performed  a  cure.  In 
the  first  case,  said  the  court,  "  the  parties  that  brought  the 
assumpsit  did  the  meritorious  act,  though  the  promise  was  made 
to  another  " ;  and,  in  the  second  case,  it  was  said  that  "  the  near- 
ness of  the  relation  gives  the  daughter  the  benefit  of  the  considera- 
tion performed  by  her  father."  The  latter  reason,  which  is 
plainly  inspired  by  the  equitable  conception,  was  the  ground  of 
the  decision  in  Dutton  v.  Poole  2  (1677).  In  that  case  it  was  held 
that  a  promise,  made  by  a  son  to  his  father,  to  pay  ^1000  to  his 
sister,  could  be  enforced  by  the  sister.  Scroggs,  C.J.,  said  that 
"  there  was  such  apparent  consideration  of  affection  from  the  father 
to  his  children,  for  whom  nature  obliges  him  to  provide,  that  the 
consideration  and  promise  to  the  father  may  well  extend  to  the 
children."  It  is  true  that  in  1724,  in  the  case  of  Crow  v.  Rogers* 
— a  case  which  did  not  involve  a  family  settlement — Bourne  v. 
Mason  was  followed,  and  a  stranger  to  the  consideration  was  not 
allowed  to  sue.  But  it  is  clear  that,  as  the  law  stood  at  the  end 
of  the  seventeenth  century,  ideas  derived  from  the  equitable  con- 
ception of  consideration  had  introduced  a  considerable  exception 
to  the  rule  that  consideration  must  move  from  the  promisee,  which 
tended  to  obscure  the  common  law  doctrine.4      It  was  not  till 

1  Below  18  and  n.  3. 

2  2  Lev.  211 ;  we  see  the  same  confusion  in  Parker,  C.J.'s,  judgment  in  Mitchel  v. 
Reynolds  (1711)  1  P.  Wms.  at  p.  193. 

8  1  Stra.  592  ;  cp.  Butcher  v.  Andrews  (1699)  Carth.  446  where  a  plaintiff,  who 
brought  assumpsit  against  a  father  for  money  lent  to  the  son  at  the  father's  request, 
was  not  allowed  to  recover ;  Holt,  C.J.,  said  "  if  it  had  been  an  indebitatus  for  so 
much  money  paid  by  the  plaintiff  at  the  request  of  the  defendant  unto  his  son,  it  might 
have  been  good,  for  then  it  would  be  the  father's  debt,  and  not  his  son's ;  but  when 
the  money  is  lent  to  the  son,  'tis  his  proper  debt,  and  not  the  father's." 

4  For  another  curious  confusion  between  the  equitable  and  common  law  use  of 
the  term  see  the  judgment  of  Parker,  C.J.,  in  Mitchel  v.  Reynolds  (1711)  1  P.  Wms. 
at  p.  193,  cited  below  62  and  n.  1. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       13 

the  decisions  of  the  nineteenth  century  1  that  this  obscurity  was 
removed  ;  and,  as  we  shall  now  see,  its  effect  was  increased  by  the 
second  of  the  two  causes  which  hindered  the  clear  perception  of 
this  principle. 

(ii)  The  disturbing  influence  of  the  idea,  derived  from  the 
competence  of  the  actions  of  debt  and  account,  that  a  person  not 
a  party  to  an  agreement  may  take  a  benefit  thereunder. 

We  have  seen  that  if  money  were  paid  by  A  to  B  for  the  use 
of  C,  C  could  sue  by  action  of  debt  or  account ; 2  and  that,  in  the 
seventeenth  century,  he  could  make  use  of  the  action  of  indebitatus 
assumpsit3  Thus  in  165 1,  in  the  case  of  Starkey  v.  Mi'//*  a 
father  gave  goods  to  his  son  in  consideration  that  the  son  should 
pay  the  plaintiff  £20.  The  objection  that  there  was  no  considera- 
tion moving  from  the  promisee  was  overruled;  and  Rolle,  C.J., 
said,  "  that  there  was  a  plain  contract,  because  the  goods  were 
given  for  the  benefit  of  the  plaintiff  though  the  contract  be  not 
between  him  and  the  defendant,  and  he  may  well  have  an  action 
upon  the  case,5  for  here  is  a  promise  in  law  made  to  the  plaintiff, 
though  there  be  not  a  promise  in  fact  etc.,  and  there  is  a  debt 
here ;  and  the  assumpsit  is  good."  It  would  seem,  too,  from  a 
dictum  of  Holt's,  that  he  agreed  with  this  reasoning.6 

(iii)  The  fact  that  the  lawyers  considered  that  benefit  to  the 
promisor-defendant  was,  equally  with  detriment  to  the  promisee- 
plaintiff,  a  valid  consideration,  tended  to  obscure  the  fact  that  such 
benefit  ought  only  to  have  been  considered  a  consideration,  if  it 
moved  from,  and  so  was  a  detriment  to,  the  promisee-plaintiff. 
Rolle,  C.J.s',  judgment  in  Starkey  v.  Mi//"'  exhibits  clear  traces 
of  this  confusion.  We  shall  now  see  that  the  confusion  so  caused 
has  tended  to  obscure  the  application  of  the  rule  that  consideration 
may  be  executed  or  executory,  but  cannot  be  past. 

(3)  Consideration  may  be  executory  or  executed,  but  it  cannot  be 
past. 

The  terms  executed  and  executory  are  obviously  apt  terms  to 
describe  the  cases  where  the  consideration  for  a  promise  has  been 
fulfilled,  and  where  it  has  not  They  were  applied  to  express  this 
difference  between  considerations  in  1 597,  though  not  in  connec- 
tion with  the  law  of  contract ; 8  and,  as  soon  as  the  scope  of  as- 
sumpsit was  extended,  so  that  by  it  wholly  executory  contracts 
could  be  enforced,  they  begin  to  be  used  to  express  this  difference 

1  Below  40.  *  Vol.  iii  425-428. 

3  Ibid  447-450  ;  below  88  seqq.  4  Style  296. 

5  The  action  on  the  case  here  brought  was  assumpsit. 

*  u  If  A  assumes  to  B  to  pay  money  to  C  upon  good  consideration,  C  may  have 

an  action  against  A  for  this  money,"  Yard  v.  Eland  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  pp.  368-369. 

7(i65i)  Style  296.  *  Barwick's  Case  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  94a. 


14       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

between  the  kinds  of  consideration  which  will  validate  a  simple 
contract.1 

Before  this  date,  however,  the  lawyers  had  begun  to  have  some 
perception  of  the  difference  between  an  executed  and  a  past  con- 
sideration. We  have  seen  that  assumpsit  lay  upon  a  contract 
where  a  detriment  had  been  actually  incurred  by  the  promisee, 
before  it  was  extended  to  enforce  a  wholly  executory  contract ; 2 
and  that,  except  in  the  case  of  the  contract  of  sale,3  debt  would 
not  lie  unless  a  quid  pro  quo  had  been  actually  received  by  the 
defendant.4  The  lawyers,  therefore,  were  obliged  to  discriminate 
between  the  performance  of  an  act  which  would  support  a  promise, 
and  the  performance  of  an  act  which  would  not.  Thus  they  were 
obliged  to  recognize  the  rule  that  the  gift  of  the  quid  pro  quo,  or 
the  incurring  of  the  detriment,  must  be  so  connected  with  the  pro- 
mise that  they  formed  substantially  one  transaction.  In  other 
words,  the  distinction  between  an  executed  consideration  which 
would,  and  a  past  consideration  which  would  not  support  a  promise, 
had  been  forced  upon  their  attention  in  connection,  both  with  the 
action  of  debt,  and  the  action  of  assumpsit.  It  is  clear  that  St. 
Germain  considered  that  a  promise  given  in  return  for  a  wholly 
past  act  not  done  in  contemplation  of  the  promise,  though  it  might 
create  a  moral  obligation,  could  not  be  united  with  the  promise  so 
as  to  make  the  promise  actionable.5 

This  principle  was  laid  down  in  the  case  of  Andrew  v.  Boughey  6 
in  1553,  and  it  was  made  the  basis  of  the  decision  in  the  case  of 
Hunt  v.  Bate  in  1568.7  In  that  case  the  servant  of  A  had  been 
arrested,  and  B  had  bailed  him.  A,  in  consideration  of  this 
action  by  B,  had  promised  to  indemnify  him.  It  was  held  that  no 
action  lay  upon  this  promise  because  the  consideration  for  it  was 
wholly  past ;  but  that  it  would  have  been  otherwise  if  the  act  done 

1  In  Sidenham  and  Wellington's  Case  (1585)  2  Leo.  at  p.  225  Periam,  J.,  uses 
the  term  executed  in  the  sense  of  past ;  and  in  Docket  v.  Voyel  (1602)  Cro.  Eliza. 
885  the  terms  past  and  executed  are  used  as  synonymous ;  but  in  Lamp'.eigh  v. 
Brathwait  (1616)  Hob.  at  p.  106  an  executed  consideration,  which  is  incorporated 
with  the  promise,  is  distinguished  from  a  past  consideration,  which,  not  being  so  in- 
corporated, does  not  validate  a  contract ;  the  fact  that  the  term  "  executed  "  then  and 
later  was  used  as  a  synonym  for  "past"  has  tended  to  confuse  this  topic;  cp. 
Street,  op.  cit.  ii  83. 

2  Vol.  iii  441-442.  8  Ibid  355-356,  423,  445-446.  4  Ibid  423. 

5  "  Doctor.  But  what  hold  they  if  the  promise  be  made  for  a  thing  past,  as  I 
promise  thee  xl  li,  for  that  thou  hast  builded  me  such  a  house,  lyeth  an  action  then  ? 
Student.  They  suppose  nay,  but  he  shall  be  bound  in  conscience  to  perform  it  after 
his  intent,"  Bk.  II.  c.  24. 

6  "  Here  the  warranty  and  promise  of  the  goodness  of  the  wax  was  void  and  of 
no  force  in  law,  because  it  was  not  made  immediately  upon  the  contract  but  a  month 
after,"  Dyer  at  f.  76a. 

7  Dyer  f.  272a  ;  the  note  to  that  case  contains  a  valuable  collection  of  sixteenth 
and  early  seventeenth  century  cases  which  show  that  the  distinction  between  a  past 
and  an  executed  consideration  was  well  understood. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       15 

by  the  plaintiff  had  been  done  at  the  request  ot  the  defendant1 
In  1585  in  Sidenham  and  Worlingtori s  Case2  the  distinction  was 
laid  down  in  almost  modern  fashion  by  Rhodes,  J.3  "  If  one  serve 
me  for  a  year  and  hath  nothing  for  his  service,  and  afterwards  at 
the  end  of  a  year  I  promise  him  20  pounds  for  his  good  and  faithful 
service  ended,  he  may  have  and  maintain  an  action  upon  the  case 
upon  the  same  promise,  for  it  is  made  upon  a  good  consideration  ; 
but  if  a  servant  hath  wages  given  him,  and  his  master  ex  abundanti, 
doth  promise  him  10  pounds  more  after  his  service  ended,  he  shall 
not  maintain  an  action  for  that  1  o  pounds  upon  the  said  promise ; 
for  there  is  not  any  new  cause  or  consideration  preceding  the 
promise."  In  1636  Jones  and  Croke,  JJ.,  in  the  case  of  Townsend 
v.  Hunt,  made  a  very  similar  statement.4  Clearly  this  view  of  the 
law  facilitated  the  adaptation  of  assumpsit  to  the  sphere  of  implied 
contracts.5  If  A  does  work  or  performs  a  service  for  B  at  B's 
request,  the  work  or  the  service  can  be  regarded  as  an  executed 
consideration,  which  will  support  a  promise  to  pay. 

It  is  clear  from  these  and  other  cases  that  the  lawyers  were 
fixing  upon  the  fact  that  the  service  was  done  by  the  plaintiff  at 
the  request  of  the  defendant,  as  the  feature  which  differentiated  an 
executed  from  a  past  consideration.  Thus  we  have  seen  that  in 
Hunt  v.  Bate  it  was  said  that  if  the  master  had  first  requested  the 
plaintiff  to  bail  his  servant  it  would  have  made  all  the  difference.6 
This  distinction  was  approved  by  Periam  7  and  Rhodes,  J  J.  ,8  in 
Sidenham  and  Worlingtori s  Case ;  and  was  clearly  stated  in  its 
accepted  form  in  1616  in  the  well-known  case  of  Lampleigh  v. 
Brathwait* — "ameer  voluntary  curtesie  will  not  have  a  considera- 
tion to  uphold  an  assumpsit.  But  if  that  curtesie  were  moved  by 
a  suit  or  request  of  the  party  that  gives  the  assumpsit,  it  will  bind, 
for  the  promise  though  it  follows,  yet  is  not  naked,  but  couples 
itself  with  the  suit  before,  and  the  merits  of  the  party  procured  by 
that  suit,  which  is  the  difference." 

But  this  manner  of  stating  the  law  led  to  some  confusion  as  to 

1 "  By  the  opinion  of  the  Court  it  (the  action)  does  not  lie  in  this  matter,  because 
there  is  no  consideration  wherefore  the  defendant  should  be  charged  for  the  debt  of 
his  servant,  unless  the  master  had  first  promised  to  discharge  the  plaintiff  before  the 
enlargement  and  mainprize  made  of  his  servant,  for  the  master  did  never  make  re- 
quest to  the  plaintiff  for  his  servant  to  do  so  much,  but  he  did  it  of  his  own  head. 
But  in  another  like  action  on  the  case  brought  upon  a  promise  of  twenty  pounds  made 
to  the  plaintiff  by  the  defendant  in  consideration  that  the  plaintiff,  at  the  special  in- 
stance of  the  said  defendant,  had  taken  to  wife  the  cousin  of  the  defendant,  that  was 
good  cause,  although  the  marriage  was  executed  and  past  before  the  undertaking  and 
promise,  because  the  marriage  ensued  (upon)  the  request  of  the  defendant,"  ibid  at  ff. 
272a,  272b. 

2  2  Leo.  224.  3  Ibid  at  p.  225. 

4Cro.  Car.  408-409,  cited  below  16  n.  4;  cp.  also  Marsh  and  Rainford's  Case 
(1588)  2  Leo.  hi. 

5  Vol.  Hi  446-447.  «  Above  n.  1.  72  Leo.  at  p.  225. 

8  Ibid.  »  Hobart  105,  at  p.  106. 


16       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

the  basis  on  which  it  really  rested,  which,  as  we  shall  see,1  was  not 
cleared  up  till  the  nineteenth  century.  To  explain  how  this  con- 
fusion arose,  we  must  glance  at  the  manner  in  which  the  form  of 
assumpsit  known  as  indebitatus  assumpsit  had  been  allowed  to 
encroach  on  the  sphere  of  debt.  We  have  seen  that  Slade's  Case 2 
sanctioned  the  principle  that  the  existence  of  a  precedent  debt 
raised  an  implied  promise  to  pay  it.  The  consideration  for  the 
promise  was  the  precedent  debt.  But  this  was  clearly  a  past  con- 
sideration. This  point  was,  as  we  have  seen,  taken  in  the  case  of 
Hodge  v.  Vavisour'm  1617,  but  it  was  overruled.3  The  debt  it 
was  said  "always  continues,"  and  "the  law  will  imply  a  tacit  con- 
sideration " ;  and  it  was  compared  to  a  case  where  the  service 
was  executed  on  the  request  of  the  defendant.  Clearly  these 
reasons  were  specious  rather  than  sound.  They  were  verbal 
quibbles  put  forward  to  explain  the  undoubted  fact  that  indebitatus 
assumpsit  lay  upon  a  precedent  debt,  and  to  square  this  fact  with 
the  undoubted  rule  that  a  past  consideration  was  no  consideration. 
The  result  seems  to  have  been  that  not  only  the  case  where  a  promise 
was  made  to  pay  a  precedent  debt,  but  also  the  case  where  an  act 
was  done  on  request,  were  regarded  as  being  in  substance  excepT 
tions  to  the  rule  that  a  past  consideration  was  invalid.  For  this 
reason  the  latter  class  of  cases  were  not  treated,  as  the  earlier 
decisions  treated  them,  as  cases  of  executed  consideration,  but  as 
showing  that  a  past  consideration,  if  given  at  the  request  of  the 
plaintiff,  was  valid.4  It  was  for  this  reason  that  it  was  held,  in  the 
case  of  Hayes  v.  Warren?  in  1724,  that  if  work  was  done  by  the 
plaintiff  he  could  not  sue  on  a  subsequent  promise  to  pay,  unless  it 
was  alleged  that  the  work  was  done  at  the  request  of  the  defendant, 
or  unless  such  request  could  be  implied  by  proof  that  the  defendant 
had  had  the  benefit  of  the  work. 

It  is  obvious,  therefore,  that  the  course  which  the  decisions  had 

1  Below  38-39.  2(i6o3)  4  Co.  Rep.  92b;  vol.  iii  443-444. 

3  3  Bulstr.  222 ;  above  g. 

4  This  is  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Townsend  v.  Hunt  (1636)  Cro.  Car.  408 ;  in 
that  case  the  defendant's  wife  was  an  executrix  and  as  such  liable  to  pay  a  legacy  of 
£60  to  the  plaintiff  when  he  came  of  age;  the  defendant  and  his  wife  paid  £53  in 
April,  and  the  plaintiff  gave  a  general  release ;  in  September  the  defendant,  in  con- 
sideration that  the  plaintiff  had  at  his  request  given  this  release,  promised  to  pay  the 
remaining  £j;  Jones  and  Croke,  JJ.,  held  that  the  contract  was  valid,  "for  if  this 
promise  had  been  made  at  the  time  of  the  release  made,  it  had  been  clearly  a  good 
promise  and  a  good  consideration  ;  then,  being  made  after  the  release,  forasmuch  as 
the  release  is  made  at  the  defendant's  request,  and  the  defendant  hath  the  continuance 
of  the  benefit  thereof,  the  promise  upon  this  consideration  is  good  enough  "  ;  after  the 
verdict  the  exception  that  the  consideration  was  past  was  again  moved,  "sed  non 
allocatur ;  because  it  was  made  at  the  defendant's  request  "  ;  note  the  recurrence  of 
the  idea  that  consideration  may  consist  in  a  benefit  to  the  promisor-defendant. 

6Stra.  933 — "it  was  objected  that  this  was  a  past  consideration;  and  not  being 
laid  to  be  done  at  the  request  of  the  defendant,  it  could  be  no  consideration  to  raise  an 
assumpsit." 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       17 

taken  in  the  seventeenth  century  had  tended,  firstly,  to  obscure  the 
relations  between  executed  and  past  consideration  ;  and,  secondly, 
to  indicate  that  the  rule  that  a  past  consideration  was  invalid  was 
a  rule  which  admitted  of  exceptions.  The  rule  that  a  precedent 
debt  would  support  an  action  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  was  a  clear 
exception  ;  and,  if  it  is  argued  that  the  consideration  is  sufficient 
because  the  man  who  owed  the  debt  ought  to  pay  it,  it  is  clear 
that  the  acceptance  of  this  argument  will  mean  the  admission  of 
something  very  like  moral  obligation  as  a  valid  consideration.1  It 
is  clear,  too,  that  the  decisions  which  made  for  exceptions  to  the 
rule  that  consideration  must  move  from  the  promisee,  and  especially 
the  decisions  which  allowed  a  person,  not  a  party  to  a  contract,  to^ 
sue  on  a  contract  made  for  his  benefit,2  tend  in  the  same  direction,  j 
All  this,  as  we  shall  see  later,  tended  to  obscure  the  logical  de-  \ 
velopment  of  the  doctrine  from  its  procedural  basis  in  assumpsit. 
But  at  this  point  we  must  consider,  in  the  two  following  sections, 
the  development  of  certain  other  rules  which  emerged  in  the 
seventeenth  century.  Here  again  we  shall  see  conflicting  tendencies 
at  work  which  prevented  any  final  settlement  of  the  law  during 
this  period. 

(4)  Consideration  need  not  be  adequate  but  it  must  be  certain. 

The  law  has  never  attempted  to  adjudicate  upon  the  adequacy 
of  a  consideration.  That  is  a  matter  for  the  parties  to  the  con- 
tract. If  a  person  chooses  to  make  an  extravagant  promise  for  an 
inadequate  consideration  it  is  his  own  affair.3  Thus  in  1587,  in 
the  case  of  Sturlyn  v.  Albany*  it  was  said  that  "when  a  thing  is 
to  be  done  by  the  plaintiff,  be  it  never  so  small,  this  is  a  sufficient 
consideration  to  ground  an  action"  ;  and  this  principle  is  an  ac- 
cepted doctrine  of  our  modern  law.  But,  though  the  consideration 
need  not  be  adequate,  it  must  be  sufficiently  definite  for  the  court 
to  see  that  it  really  exists.  Thus  it  was  said  in  1553  that,  "if  I 
bargain  with  you  that  I  will  give  you  for  your  land  as  much  as  it 
is  reasonably  worth,  this  is  void  for  default  of  certainty ;  but  if  the 
judging  of  this  be  referred  to  a  third  person,  and  he  adjudge  it, 

1  Thus  in  Bosden  v.  Thinn  (1603)  Cro.  Jac.  at  p.  19  the  court  decided  in  favour 
of  the  plaintiff,  "  because  Roberts,  upon  the  plaintiff's  undertaking  at  the  defendant's 
request,  had  credit  given  him  by  Fludd;  and  that  the  plaintiff  was  damnified  by  reason 
thereof,  which  in  conscience  the  defendant  ought  to  satisfy ;  that  the  consideration  is 
sufficient  and  not  past  "  ;  cp.  the  Doctor  and  Student  cited  above  14  n.  5. 

8  Above  12. 

5  "  The  idea,"  says  Sir  F.  Pollock,  "  is  characteristic  not  only  in  English  positive 
law  but  in  the  English  school  of  theoretical  jurisprudence  and  politics.  Hobbes  says  : 
1  the  value  of  all  things  contracted  for  is  measured  by  the  appetite  of  the  contractors, 
and  therefore  the  just  value  is  that  which  they  be  contented  to  give,'  "  Contracts 
(9th  ed.)  186-187. 

4Cro.  Eliza.  67;  cp.  Bunniworth  v.  Gibbs  (1654)  Style  419  per  Rolle,  C.J. 
VOL.  VIII.— 2 


18       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

then  it  is  good."  x  In  1 588  2  and  1600 3  it  was  held  that  love  and 
natural  affection  were  not  considerations  upon  which  an  assumpsit 
could  be  grounded.  In  1636  it  was  held  that  a  promise  to  forbear 
"aliquo  tempore"  was  void  for  uncertainty.4 

It  is  easy  to  state  this  principle,  but  difficult  to  apply  it  to 
concrete  cases  which  come  near  the  line ;  and  it  is  clear  that  this 
difficulty  will  be  enormously  increased,  if  once  the  law  begins  to 
develop  those  lines  of  cases  which  tended  to  mix  up  moral  obliga- 
tion and  consideration.  No  doubt  it  is  easy  to  say  that  one  test  of 
certainty  is  to  be  obtained  by  asking  whether  the  act  or  forbearance 
had  a  definite  value.  But  this  solution  merely  shifts  the  difficulty, 
for,  as  we  shall  now  see,  the  law  had  no  very  clear  ideas  as  to  what 
acts  or  things  it  accounted  of  sufficiently  definite  value. 

(5)  Consideration  must  be  an  act  or  forbearance  of  some  value 
in  the  eye  of  the  law. 

The  question  whether  or  not  an  act  or  forbearance  is  of  suf- 
ficient value  in  the  eye  of  the  law,  was  discussed  during  this  period 
chiefly  in  three  classes  of  cases  :  (i)  when  the  promise  was  made  in 
consideration  of  a  forbearance  to  prosecute  a  groundless  claim  ;  (ii) 
when  a  promise  was  made  by  a  creditor  to  his  debtor  that,  in  con- 
sideration that  the  debtor  would  pay  or  promise  to  pay  his  debt 
wholly  or  in  part,  the  creditor  would  release  him  ;  and  (iii)  when 
a  promise  was  made  by  a  third  person  that  he  would  do  something 
for  one  of  the  parties  to  a  subsisting  valid  contract,  if  that  party 
would  perform  or  promise  to  perform  his  duty  under  the  contract.5 

(i)  Promises  made  in  consideration  of  a  forbearance  to  prosecute 
a  groundless  claim.6 

It  was  settled  in  1  568,  in  the  case  of  Stone  v.  Wythipol,1  that 
forbearance  to  prosecute  an  invalid  claim  was  no  consideration. 
In  that  case  the  executor  of  an  infant  testator  promised  to  pay  his 
testator's  debt,  if  the  creditor  would  forbear  to  sue.  It  was  held 
that,  as  he  could  not  have  sued  for  this  debt  because  the  testator 
was  an  infant,  the  promise  of  the  executor  to  pay  was  based  on  no 
consideration.  Coke's  argument,  to  which  the  court  assented,  was 
as  follows :  "  Every  consideration  that  doth  charge  the  defendant 
in  an  assumpsit  must  be  to  the  benefit  of  the  defendant  or  charge 

1  Mervyn  v.  Lyds,  Dyer  at  f.  91  a. 

2  Harford  and  Gardiner's  Case  2  Leo.  30. 

3  Brett  v.  J.S.  and  his  Wife,  Cro.  Eliza.  756 — "  Natural  affection  of  itself  is  not  a 
sufficient  consideration  to  ground  an  assumpsit;  for  although  it  be  sufficient  to  raise 
a  use,  yet  it  is  not  sufficient  to  ground  an  action  without  an  express  quid  pro  quo." 

4  Tolson  v.  Clark,  Cro.  Car.  438. 

6  On  these  topics  generally  see  Ames,  Two  Theories  of  Consideration,  Lectures 
323-353. 

8  See  Ames,  op.  cit.  325-327.  7  Cro.  Eliza.  126. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES      19 

of  the  plaintiff,  and  no  case  can  be  put  out  of  this  rule.  And  this 
contract  by  the  infant  was  void ;  and  staying  of  suit  is  no  benefit 
to  the  defendant,  nor  any  charge  to  the  plaintiff,  more  than  was 
before."  This  decision  was  followed  in  a  long  line  of  cases;1  and 
substantially  the  same  reasoning  as  that  used  by  Coke  was  used  by 
Tindal,  C.J.,  in  1846.2  But,  before  this  date,  it  had  ceased  to  be 
possible  to  state  the  principle  quite  so  absolutely.  It  had  been 
decided  in  1821  that  forbearance  to  prosecute  a  suit  already  in- 
stituted, when  the  law  was  doubtful,  was  a  valid  consideration  for 
a  promise.3  This  view  was  approved  in  1861,  and  extended  to  a 
forbearance  to  institute  proceedings  to  establish  a  claim  which  there 
was  a  bona  fide  intention  to  make  the  subject  of  litigation.4  Finally, 
in  1870,  in  the  case  of  Callisher  v.  Bischoffsheim?  it  was  held  that 
forbearance  to  prosecute  a  bona  fide  claim  was  a  good  consideration, 
though  the  claim  was  in  fact  baseless.  It  would  seem,  therefore, 
that  the  old  principle  only  applies  to  a  forbearance  to  prosecute  a 
claim  which  the  claimant  knows  to  be  baseless.6 

(ii)  During  this  period  a  much  discussed  question  was  the 
validity  of  a  promise  made  by  a  creditor  to  his  debtor  that,  in 
consideration  of  the  debtor  paying  or  promising  to  pay  the  whole 
or  part  of  his  debt,  the  creditor  would  release  him.  During  this 
period  opinion  was  fairly  evenly  divided  upon  this  question.  Let 
us  look  at  the  cases,  firstly  upon  the  question  whether  the  actual 
payment  of  the  whole  or  part  of  an  existing  debt,  and  secondly 
upon  the  question  whether  a  promise  to  pay  the  whole  or  a  part 
of  an  existing  debt,  could  be  a  good  consideration  for  a  release. 

(a)  There  were  two  lines  of  reasoning  which  led  the  courts  to 
deny  that  a  part  payment  by  a  debtor  was  a  consideration  for  a 
promise  by  his  creditor  to  release  him. 


1  See  the  list  collected  by  Ames,  op.  cit.  325  n.  2. 

*  "  In  order  to  constitute  a  binding  promise,  the  plaintiff  must  show  a  good  con- 
sideration, something  beneficial  to  the  defendant,  or  detrimental  to  the  plaintiff. 
Detrimental  to  the  plaintiff  it  cannot  be  if  he  has  no  cause  of  action ;  and  beneficial 
to  the  defendant  it  cannot  be ;  for,  in  contemplation  of  law,  the  defence  upon  such  an 
admitted  state  of  facts  must  be  successful,  and  the  defendant  will  recover  costs,  which 
must  be  assumed  to  be  a  full  compensation  for  all  the  legal  damage  he  may  sustain," 
Wade  v.  Simeon  2  C.B.  at  p.  564. 

3  Longridge  v.  Dorville  5  B.  and  Aid.  117. 

4  Cook  v.  Wright  1  B.  and  S.  559.  5  L.R.  4  Q.B.  449. 

•  "  Every  day  a  compromise  is  affected  on  the  ground  that  the  party  making  it 
has  a  chance  of  succeeding  in  it,  and  if  he  bona  fide  believes  he  has  a  fair  chance* of 
success,  he  has  a  reasonable  ground  for  suing,  and  his  forbearance  to  sue  will  con- 
stitute a  good  consideration.  ...  It  would  be  another  matter  if  a  person  made  a 
claim  which  he  knew  to  be  unfounded,  and,  by  a  compromise  derived  an  advantage 
under  it;  in  that  case  his  conduct  would  be  fraudulent,"  per  Cockburn,  C.J.,  L.R. 
4  Q.B.  at  p.  452;  "It  seems  to  me  that  if  an  intending  litigant  bona  fide  forbears  a 
right  to  litigate  a  question  of  law  or  fact,  which  it  is  not  vexatious  or  frivolous  to 
litigate,  he  does  give  up  something  of  value,"  Miles  v.  New  Zealand  Alford  Estate  Co. 
(1886)  32  CD.  at  p.  291,  per  Bowen,  L.J. 


20      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

Firstly,  after  some  hesitation  in  the  fifteenth  century,1  the 
opinion  of  Brian,  C.J.,  to  the  effect  that  a  smaller  sum  cannot  be 
a  satisfaction  for  a  larger,2  had  come  to  be  generally  approved  in 
the  sixteenth  century.3  The  rule  on  this  point  was  stated  in  its 
final  form  in  PinneCs  Case  in  1602  : 4  "  Payment  of  a  lesser  sum 
on  the  day  in  satisfaction  of  a  greater  cannot  be  any  satisfaction 
for  the  whole,  because  it  appears  to  the  judges  that  by  no 
possibility  a  lesser  sum  can  be  a  satisfaction  to  the  plaintiff  for  a 
greater  sum ;  but  the  gift  of  a  horse  hawk  or  robe  etc.,  in  satis- 
faction is  good."  This  really  amounts  to  the  arithmetic  proposition 
that  a  lesser  sum  cannot  be  satisfaction  for  a  greater.5  It  is  a  rule 
relating  to  the  discharge  of  contract,  which  was  evolved  in  the 
sphere  of  the  action  of  debt,  and  naturally  followed  from  the 
limitations  of  that  action.  It  is  not,  and  it  could  not  be,  based 
upon  the  view  that  such  an  agreement  was  not  enforceable  by 
action  of  assumpsit,  because  there  was  no  consideration  for  it,  for 
the  simple  reason  that  the  action  of  assumpsit  was  only  just 
beginning  to  develop,  and  the  doctrine  of  consideration  was  as  yet 
wholly  undeveloped.6  In  fact,  till  the  expansion  of  assumpsit  to 
remedy  purely  executory  contracts,  it  was  inevitable  that  this  ques- 
tion should  be  regarded  solely  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  action  of 
debt.  A  mere  agreement  to  discharge  was  not  actionable.  It  only 
became  actionable  when  the  thing  for  which  the  discharge  was 
promised  was  done ;  for,  till  then,  the  promisor  had  no  quid  pro 
quo.  But  if  that  thing  was  less  than  the  party  doing  it  was 
liable  to  do,  where  was  the  quid  pro  quo  ?  As  Brian,  C.J. ,  said, 
"  It  is  agreed  that  the  agreement  merely  is  nothing  to  the  purpose, 
but  the  agreement  coupled  with  the  satisfaction ;  so  that  the  per- 
formance of  the  agreement  is  the  substance  of  the  plea."  7 

Secondly,  we  have  seen  that  the  Roman  rule,  that  a  contractual 
obligation  ought  to  be  discharged  by  the  same  formalities  as  those 
by  which  it  had  been  made,  had  been  received  by  the  common 
law.8     It  followed  that  a  contract,  which  purported  to  discharge 

1Y.B.  33  Hy.  VI.  Mich.  pi.  32  (p.  48)  per  Danvers,  J.,  cited  An.es,  op.  cit.  329; 
and  in  Y.B.  10  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  4,  Fineux,  J.,  expressed  the  same  opinion — "  Semble 
que  il  n'y  ad  diversite  perenter  le  cas  de  satisfaction  de  concord  in  argent  ou  d'un 
cheval.  Car  nien  obstant  que  le  sum  in  concord  soit  moins  que  le  sum  in  demande  ; 
uncore  quand  le  debtee  (i.e.  creditor)  ce  ad  receu  per  son  agreement  demesne,  c'est 
ausey  bon  satisfaction  a  luy  en  Ley  come  receit  d'un  chose  d'autre  nature"  ;  to  the 
same  effect  Perkins,  Profitable  Book  §  749  (ed.  1642),  who  notices  the  divergence  of 
opinion  on  the  point. 

2  "  L'accion  est  port  sur  xxl.,  et  le  concord  que  il  paiera  forsque  x/.,  lequel  appert 
estre  nul  satisfaction  de  xxl.,  car  paiement  de  xl.,  ne  poit  estre  paiement  de  xxZ.  .  .  . 
Mes  si  fuit  du  cheval,  quel  cheval  est  paye  accordant  al  concord,  c'est  bon  satisfaction ; 
car  non  appert  le  quel  le  cheval  vault  plus  ou  moins  que  le  som  en  demande,"  Y.B. 
10  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  4. 

3(1563)  Dalison  49  ;  (1587)  4  Leo.  81.  45  Co.  Rep.  117a. 

8  Ames,  op.  cit.  330-331.  6  Ibid  330. 

7  Y.B.  10  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  4.  8  Vol.  ii  277  n.  10. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       21 

an  existing  contractual  obligation,  must  be  based  on  consideration. 
But  if  A,  being  under  a  contractual  obligation  to  pay  £10  to  B, 
agrees  with  B  that,  if  B  will  discharge  him,  he  will  pay  £5,  what 
consideration  is  there  for  B's  promise  ?  Clearly  A  has  incurred  no 
detriment  by  the  making  of  such  a  promise.  It  follows  that  such 
a  consideration  is  not  valid.  This  reasoning  was  followed  in 
Richards  and  Bartlefs  Case  in  1584.1  In  that  case  R,  the 
executrix  of  A,  sued  B  for  the  price  of  corn  delivered  by  her 
testator.  B  pleaded  that,  after  the  contract  had  been  made,  R 
agreed  that,  because  the  corn  had  been  lost  by  a  tempest,  he 
would  charge  only  part  of  the  price ;  and  that  he  had  always  been 
ready  to  pay  this  part  of  the  price.  The  whole  court  decided  in 
favour  of  the  plaintiff,  "  because  there  is  here  not  any  consideration 
set  forth  in  the  bar,  by  reason  whereof  the  plaintiff  should  dis- 
charge the  defendant  of  this  matter,  for  no  profit  but  damage 
comes  to  the  plaintiff  by  this  agreement,  and  the  defendant  is  not 
put  to  any  labour  or  charge  by  it,  therefore  here  is  not  any  agree- 
ment to  bind  the  plaintiff."  This  decision  was  followed  by  cases 
decided  in  1591,2  and  1597.3  In  the  latter  of  these  cases  it  was 
held  that  the  payment  of  the  same  sum  as  that  which  the  plaintiff 
was  liable  to  pay,  was  no  consideration  for  a  further  promise  by 
the  defendant. 

It  follows,  therefore,  that  whether  we  regard  the  rule  as  a  rule 
relating  to  the  acts  which  will  operate  as  a  discharge,  or  whether 
we  regard  it  as  a  rule  regulating  the  validity  of  a  contract  to  dis- 
charge the  party  liable,  the  same  result  is  produced.  The 
payment  of  the  whole  or  a  part  will  operate  neither  as  a  discharge, 
nor  will  it  be  a  consideration  for  an  agreement  to  discharge. 

So  far  the  law  is  clear.  The  payment  of  the  whole  or  part  of 
the  sum  due  cannot  be  consideration  for  a  further  promise,  because 
such  payment  is  no  detriment  to  the  promisee.  But  in  the 
sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  the  law  was  not  finally  settled 
on  these  lines.  There  is  another  line  of  cases  in  which  the  judges, 
looking  rather  at  the  benefit  derived  by  the  promisor  in  getting 
speedy  payment  or  payment  without  action,  held  such  payment  to 
be  a  valid  consideration  for  a  promise  to  release  the  debt.  They 
held  therefore  that,  though  as  decided  in  PinnePs  Case,6  payment 
of  a  lesser  sum  was  no  satisfaction  of  a  greater,  yet  the  payment 
of  such  lesser  sum  might  be  a  valid  consideration  for  a  promise  to 
give  a  release,  or  to  do  some  other  act.  Thus  in  1 595,  in  the  case 
of  Reynolds  v.  Pinhowe?  the  defendant  had  recovered  .£5  from  the 

1  1  Leo.  19  ;  cp.  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  98-99. 

2  Greenleaf  v.  Barker,  Cro.  Eliza.  193. 

3  Dixon  v.  Adams,  Cro.  Eliza.  538. 

5  5  Co.  Rep.  117a.  5Cro.  Eliza.  429. 


22       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

plaintiff.  In  consideration  of  £4  paid  to  him  by  the  plaintiff,  the 
defendant  promised  to  acknowledge  satisfaction  of  the  judgment. 
The  court  held  the  contract  valid,  "  for  it  is  a  benefit  unto  him  to 
have  it  without  suit  or  charge."  The  same  view  was  put  forward 
by  Coke,  C.J.,  in  161 7,  in  the  case  of  Bagge  v.  Slade.1  "If,"  he 
said,  "a  man  be  bound  to  another  by  a  bill  in  £1,000  and  he  pays 
unto  him  £500  in  discharge  of  this  bill,  the  which  he  accepts  of 
accordingly,  and  doth  upon  this  assume  and  promise  to  deliver  up 
unto  him  his  said  bill  of  £1,000,  this  £500  is  no  satisfaction  of 
the  £1,000,  but  yet  this  is  good  and  sufficient  to  make  a  good 
promise,  and  upon  a  good  consideration,  because  he  hath  paid 
money — £500 — and  he  hath  no  remedy  for  this  again."  Possibly 
Coke  may  have  considered  that  the  payment  was  a  consideration 
because,  if  such  payment  could  have  been  resisted,  it  was  a  detri- 
ment to  the  promisee ;  but  I  think  that  his  dominant  idea  was 
that  the  payee  has  got  the  money,  and  that  this  benefit  to  him 
should  be  a  consideration — as  he  said  elsewhere  in  the  same  case, 
"  I  have  never  seen  it  otherwise,  but  when  one  draws  money  from 
another,  that  this  should  be  good  consideration  to  raise  a  promise." 
There  are  other  cases  decided  in  the  seventeenth  century  in  which 
the  same  reasoning  was  used  ; 2  and  we  shall  see  that  it  was  not 
till  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  that  it  was  finally 
settled  that  the  payment  by  a  debtor  to  his  creditor  of  a  part  of  a 
sum  due,  cannot  be  a  consideration  for  a  promise  by  the  creditor.3 
(b)  As  soon  as  it  was  recognized  that  a  promise  given  for  a 
promise  was  a  valid  consideration,4  it  is  difficult  to  resist  the 
conclusion  that  a  promise  by  a  debtor  to  pay  part  of  a  debt  to  his 
creditor,  ought  to  be  a  consideration  for  a  promise  by  the  creditor 
to  release  him.  This  view  seems  to  have  been  taken  in  the  earlier 
half  of  the  seventeenth  century.  In  1602,  in  the  case  of  Goring 
v.  Goring,5  an  agreement  by  an  executor  to  discharge  a  debtor  of 
his  testator  who  owed  £205,  in  consideration  of  a  promise  by  the 
debtor  to  pay  £150  in  instalments,  though  admitted  to  be  no 
valid  satisfaction,  was  held  to  be  a  valid  agreement,  as  it  was 
promise  against  promise.6  Similarly  Comyns  states  that  "an 
accord  with  mutual  promises  to  perform  is  good,  though  the  thing 

J3  Bulstr.  162. 

2  Flight  v.  Crasden  (1625)  Cro.  Car.  8  (payment  of  the  whole) ;  Johnson  v.  Astell 
(1667)  1  Lev.  198  (payment  of  less) ;  Anon.  (1675)  1  Ventris  258  (payment  of  the 
whole) ;  and  see  other  cases  cited  by  Ames,  op.  cit.  331-332. 

8  Below  40.  4  Vol.  iii  445.  8  Yelv.  n. 

6  "  And  (per  Curiam)  the  consideration  alleged  is  sufficient  for  another  reason; 
for  although  the  plaintiff  has  not  shown  that  he  has  discharged  the  defendant  of  the 
£205,  yet  if  the  defendant  should  afterwards  be  charged  with  it,  he  might  have 
assumpsit  against  the  plaintiff;  for  the  plaintiff  agreeing  to  take  £150  for  £205  is  a 
promise  on  his  part,  and  so  one  promise  against  another,"  ibid ;  cp.  Ames,  op.  cit. 
348. 


IN  XVITH  AND  XVIITH  CENTURIES       23 

be  not  performed  at  the  time  of  action  ;  for  the  party  has  a  remedy 
to  compel  the  performance"1  We  shall  see  that  it  was  not  till 
the  following  century,  that,  not  without  some  conflict  of  opinion, 
it  came  to  be  thought  that  promises  of  this  kind,  though  mutual, 
were  inoperative  to  operate  as  a  satisfaction  of  the  original  debt ; 2 
and  that  the  view  that  in  this  case  the  mutual  promises  are  not 
considerations  for  each  other,  derives  its  strength  from  cases  in 
which  the  judges  had  failed  to  adapt  the  old  rules  as  to  accord 
and  satisfaction,  to  the  new  situation  created  by  the  rise  of  the 
wholly  executory  contract3  But  we  shall  see  that  there  is 
authority  to  the  contrary,  and  that  the  law  on  this  point  is  not  yet 
wholly  settled.4 

(iii)  A  somewhat  analogous  problem  to  that  last  discussed 
arises,  when  a  promise  is  made  by  a  third  person  that  he  will  do 
something  for  one  of  the  parties  to  a  subsisting  valid  contract,  if 
that  party  will  perform  or  promise  to  perform  his  duty  under  the 
contract5  Such  contracts  are  of  course  of  comparatively  rare 
occurrence ;  but,  during  this  period,  at  least  two  cases  arose  in 
which  the  problem  was  discussed.  Both  were  cases  in  which  the 
consideration  for  the  promise  by  the  third  person  was,  not  the 
actual  performance  by  the  party  to  the  contract  of  his  duty  under 
that  contract,  but  a  counter  promise  by  that  party  to  perform  his 
duty.6  In  1600,  in  the  case  of  Sherwood  v.  Woodward?  the 
plaintiff  sold  cheeses  to  the  defendant's  son.  The  defendant,  "in 
consideration  the  plaintiff  would  deliver  the  said  cheeses  to  his 
said  son,  assumed,  that  if  the  son  did  not  pay  for  them  then  he 
would."  The  son  did  not  pay,  and  the  plaintiff  sued  on  this 
promise.  In  arrest  of  judgment  it  was  moved  "that  this  was  not 
any  consideration ;  for  it  is  no  more  than  what  the  law  appoints 
to  deliver  that  which  he  sold."  The  court  over-ruled  this  objection 
and  held  the  consideration  valid.  In  the  case  of  Bagge  v.  Slade? 
"two  men  were  bound  in  a  bond  for  the  debt  of  a  third  man ;  the 
obligation  being  forfeited,  so  that  they  both  of  them  were  liable 
to  pay  this ;  the  plaintiff  here  in  this  writ  of  error  said  to  the 
other,  pay  you  all  the  debt,  and  I  will  pay  you  the  moyety  of  this 
again,  the  which  he  paid  accordingly,  and  so  made  his  request  to 
have  a  repayment  made  to  him  of  the  moyety  according  to  his 
promise,  which  to  do  he  refused."  Thereupon  the  plaintiff  sued 
for  the  moiety,  and  judgment  was  given  for  him. 

1  Digest  Accord  B  4.  s  Below  40-41,  83-85. 

»  Below  83-85.  *  Below  85. 

5  On  this  topic  there  has  been  much  discussion  ;  see'Ames,  op.  cit.  327-329,  340- 
34S;  Wiliiston  H.L.R.viii  27-38;  Langdell,  H.L.R/xiv  496-508 ;  Pollock,  Contracts 
(9th  ed.)  197-202,  and  L.Q.R.  xvii  419-422;  Street,  op.  cit.^116-120. 

6  But  Ames,  op.  cit.  327,  takes  the  view  that  in  Bagge  v.  Slade  3  Bulstr.  162,  the 
consideration  was  the  performance;  for  the  reasons  given  below  24,  I  do  not  agree. 

7  Cro  Eliza.  700.  8  (1616)  3  Bulstr.  162, 


24       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

Now  it  is  reasonably  clear  that  both  these  cases  were  cases  of 
promise  for  promise.  It  is  clear,  in  the  first  case,  that,  when 
promise  was  made,  the  cheese  was  not  yet  delivered  ;  and,  in  the 
second  case,  that,  when  the  promise  was  made,  the  money  had 
not  yet  been  paid.  For  this  reason  no  valid  objection  can  be 
taken  to  the  actual  decisions  in  these  cases.  A  promise  for  a 
promise  was  clearly  a  valid  consideration — why  should  not  a 
promise  to  perform  a  legally  enforceable  duty  already  owed  to  a 
third  person  be  a  good  consideration  for  a  counter  promise  ?  We 
shall  see  that,  unlike  the  case  of  a  promise  by  a  debtor  to  pay  a 
sum  less  than  the  debt  owed,  in  consideration  of  a  counter  promise 
to  give  a  release,  no  body  of  opinion  excluding  this  particular  sort 
of  promise  has  grown  up.1 

But  in  both  these  cases  the  court  went  a  good  deal  further 
than  this.  In  both  they  were  inclined  to  take  the  same  view  as 
was  taken  in  that  line  of  cases  in  which  it  was  held  that  a  pay- 
ment of  part  of  a  debt  might  be  good  consideration  for  a  promise 
to  release  the  whole ; 2  for  in  both  they  assigned,  as  the  reason  for 
their  view  that  such  payment  was  a  valid  consideration,  the  fact 
that  it  was  a  benefit  to  the  creditor  to  get  the  money.  We  have 
seen  that  this  view  is  indicated  in  Coke's  remarks  in  the  case  of 
Bagge  v.  Slade ; 3  and  it  is  even  more  clearly  apparent  in  the 
remarks  of  Gawdy  and  Fenner,  JJ.,  in  the  case  of  Sherwood  v. 
Woodward.  "It  is  an  ease,"  they  said,4  "to  the  bargainee  to 
have  them  without  suit,  which  peradventure  otherwise  he  could 
not  have  had.  And  although  the  bargainee  may  take  them  in 
this  case,  the  bargainor  is  not  bound  to  deliver  them ;  and  there  is 
a  new  act  done  by  him  upon  this  agreement,  and  it  is  an  ease  to 
the  vendee." 

The  development  of  these  rules,  during  the  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth  centuries,  shows  that  consideration  was  acquiring  a 
technical  meaning  in  connection  with  the  law  of  contract,  and  that 
a  doctrine  of  consideration  was  growing  up.  As  assumpsit  was 
fast  ousting  all  other  remedies  for  the  enforcement  of  contracts  it 
was  only  natural  that  the  contents  of  that  doctrine  should  be 
shaped  largely,  and  perhaps  principally,  by  the  exigencies  of  that 
remedy.  It  tended  to  be  a  reflection  of  the  conditions  which  a 
plaintiff  must  satisfy  before  he  could  succeed  in  this  action.  But, 
as  the  developments  just  described  show,  this  was  not  the  only 
influence  which  has  gone  to  the  making  of  the  doctrine.  Ideas 
derived  from  the  quid  pro  quo,  which  must  be  proved  in  order  to 
succeed  in  an  action  of  debt ;  ideas  derived  from  the  very  different 

1  Below  41.  a  Above  21-22. 

a  Above  22.  4  Cro.  Eliza.  700. 


IN  XVIIITH  &  EARLY  XIXTH  CENTS.       25 

conception  of  consideration  which  was  being  developed  by  the 
court  of  Chancery ;  and  doubts  as  to  the  invalidity  of  a  past 
consideration,  caused  jarfrely  hy  the  fart  thaf  the  past-  rnn<;irWa. 
tion  of  a  precedent  debt  was  the  foundation  of  the  action  in 
mdebijaBJ^assurnpsi^-aTT  tended  to  import  into  the  doctrine 
oTconsideration  elements,  which  led  in  practice  to  results  very 
different  from  those  which  flowed  from  the  view  that  it  was 
simply  the  sum  and  substance  of  the  conditions  which  a  plaintiff 
must  satisfy,  in  order  to  succeed  in  an  action  of  assumpsit.  We 
must  not  underrate  the  importance  of  these  elements.  We  shall 
now  see  that,  during  the  eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  centuries, 
they  came  very  near  to  ousting  the  ideas  derived  from  the 
conditions  under  which  assumpsit  lay ;  and  that  it  was  not  till  the 
second  half  of  the  nineteenth  century  that  the  latter  set  of  ideas 
prevailed,  and  that  the  doctrine  was  settled  on  its  modern  basis. 

Consideration  in  the  Eighteenth  and  Early  Nineteenth  Centuries 

During  this  period  the  doctrine  of  consideration  was  developed 
mainly  on  lines  which  ignored  its  historical  connection  with  the 
action  of  assumpsit.  More  and  more  emphasis  was  laid  upon  those 
elements  in  the  doctrine,  and  those  ideas,  which  were  derived  from 
other  sources ;  and  thus  it  became  possible  for  Lord  Mansfield 
and  his  fellow  judges  to  put  forward  theories  which  almost,  if  not 
quite,  identified  consideration  with  moral  obligation.  Thus  the 
doctrine  of  consideration  was  given  a  wholly  new  shape  which 
would,  if  it  had  become  established  as  a  part  of  the  common  law, 
have  fundamentally  altered  the  whole  theory  of  our  law  of  contract. 
At  one  time  there  was  some  likelihood  that  consideration  would 
become  of  merely  evidentiary  value ;  and  even  when  this  possibility 
had  disappeared,  it  still  remained  extremely  probable  that  its 
identification  with  moral  obligation  would  leave  it  as  vague  and 
illusory  a  test  of  the  validity  of  a  contract  as  the  continental 
"  cause."  * 

In  this  section  I  shall  describe  the  technical  lines  upon  which 
this  development  proceeded  and  indicate  its  effects  upon  the 
doctrine  of  consideration. 

The  earliest  line  of  development  started  from  the  rule  that,  if 
a  debt  was  due,  a  promise  to  pay  that  debt  would  give  rise  to  an 
action  in  indebitatus  assumpsit.2  This  principle  was  applied  to 
cases  where  the  debt  was  really  due,  but,  for  one  reason  or  another, 
it  was  not  enforceable  by  action.  As  the  debt  was  due,  it  was  no 
very  violent  departure   from    principle  to  rule   that   an  express 

1  Below  44.  »  Vol.  iii  443-444. 


26       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

promise  by  the  debtor  to  pay  it  would  remove  the  bar  to  the 
enforcement  of  the  debt.  Thus  it  was  held  in  1697  that  "  when 
the  defendant  under  age  borrowed  money  of  the  plaintiff,  and 
afterwards  at  full  age  promised  to  pay  it,  this  is  a  good  considera- 
tion for  the  promise,  and  the  defendant  shall  be  charged."  x  On 
similar  principles,  it  was  held  in  1699  that  a  promise  to  pay  a  debt 
barred  by  the  statute  of  limitation  made  the  debt  enforceable  by 
action,  and  could  be  set  up  in  answer  to  a  plea  of  the  statute ; 2 
and  the  former  ruling,  that  an  infant  could  be  sued  on  an  express 
promise  made  after  he  had  come  of  age  to  pay  a  debt  contracted 
during  infancy,  was  affirmed.3  A  further  development  of  the  same 
principle  was  made  in  1777,  in  the  case  of  Trueman  v.  Fenton* 
when  it  was  held  that  a  promise  by  a  bankrupt  to  pay  a  creditor, 
who  had  accepted  no  dividend,  was  enforceable.  The  transaction 
was  regarded  as  the  revival  of  the  old  debt,  and,  in  this  as  in  the 
other  cases,  the  old  debt  was  considered  to  be  a  sufficient  con- 
sideration for  the  subsequent  promise.5 

So  far  there  is  an  extension  of,  but  no  very  violent  departure 
from,  the  older  precedents  which  allowed  that  an  existing  debt  was 
a  good  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise.  But,  when  True- 
man  v.  Fenton  was  decided,  these  cases  were  being  made  by  Lord 
Mansfield  the  foundation  of  a  large  generalization,  which  put  their 
ratio  decidendi  on  the  very  different  ground  of  moral  obligation. 
XTlrTe~5a-me— time,  influenced  by  the  new  principles  of  mercantile 
law  which  he  was  introducing  into  the  common  law,  he  was  prepared 
to  assign  to  the  doctrine  of  consideration  a  new  and  subordinate 
position  in  the  law  of  contract.  Let  us  examine  these  two  lines  of 
approach  to  the  establishment  of  a  wholly  new  theory  of  considera- 
tion in  English  law. 

(i)   The  idea  of  moral  obligation. 

It  is  clear  from  the  judgment  in  Trueman  v.  Fenton,  that  Lord 
Mansfield  relied  far  more  on  broad  equitable  principles,  than  upon 
the  comparatively  narrow  common  law  doctrine  that  the  existence 
of  a  precedent  debt  is  a  good  consideration  for  a  promise  to  pay. 
"  The  debts  of  a  bankrupt,"  he  said,  "  are  due  in  conscience,  not- 
withstanding he  has  obtained  his  certificate  ;  and  there  is  no  honest 
man  who  does  not  discharge  them,  if  he  afterwards  has  it  in  his  power 
to  do  so.  Though  all  legal  remedy  may  be  gone  the  debts  are 
clearly  not  extinguished  in  conscience."  6     He  used  both  the  old 

1  Ball  v.  Hesketh  Comb.  381.  2Hyleing  v.  Hastings  i  Ld.  Raym.  38^. 

3  Ibid.  *  2  Cowper  544. 

5"  Then  the  case  of  Barnardiston  v.  Coupland  in  C.B.  is  in  point.  Lord  Chief 
Justice  Willes  there  says  '  that  the  revival  of  an  old  debt  is  a  sufficient  consideration.' 
That  determines  the  whole  case,"  per  Lord  Mansfield,  C.J.,  ibid  at  p.  549, 

6  Ibid  p.  548. 


IN  XVIIITH  &  EARLY  XIXTH  CENTS.       27 

cases,  which  showed  that  a  debt  barred  by  the  statute  of  limitation 
and  a  debt  irrecoverable  by  reason  of  infancy,  were  considerations 
for  a  promise  to  pay,  and  the  analogy  of  equitable  doctrines,  to 
show  that  the  courts  had  recognized  such  a  conscientious  obliga- 
tion.1 And,  though  he  based  his  judgment  to  some  extent  upon 
the  common  law  decisions,  he  relied  far  more  on  a  case  decided  by 
lord  chancellor  Parker,2  in  which  the  right  of  a  creditor  to  recover 
on  a  bond  given  by  a  bankrupt  had  been  put  wholly  on  the  ground 
of  conscience.3  This  reliance  on  equitable  decisions  was  the  more 
attractive  in  that  equity  had,  as  we  have  seen,  a  doctrine  of  con- 
sideration very  different  from  that  of  the  common  law.4  But  the 
rules  as  to  what  amounted  in  equity  to  consideration  necessarily 
shared  the  vagueness  of  many  of  the  principles  of  equity,  and,  like 
those  principles,  still  retained  many  traces  of  notions  derived  from 
abstract  morality  or  natural  reason  ; 5  and  thus  it  happened  that 
Lord  Mansfield's  bias  in  favour  of  introducing  equitable  principles 
into  the  common  law  was  eminently  calculated  to  introduce 
confusion  into  the  common  law  doctrine  of  consideration,  and, 
ultimately,  fundamental  changes  which  would  have  altered  the 
whole  of  the  common  law  theory  of  contract. 

Lord  Mansfield's  appeals  to  moral  and  natural  law  were  attrac- 
tive to  the  minds  of  the  lawyers  of  his  day  ;  and  so  the  idea  that 
a  conscientious  obligation  could  be  a  consideration  for  a  promise 
was  speedily  taken  up.  It  would  seem  that  it  was  argued  unsuc- 
cessfully in  Rann  v.  Hughes*  that  the  fact  that  an  administratrix 
had  assets  was  sufficient  consideration  for  a  promise  by  her  to  pay 
in  her  personal  capacity,  because  she  was  liable  in  conscience.  And, 
though  it  was  held  on  the  facts  of  that  case  that  there  was  no 
consideration,  Lord  Mansfield  distinguished  Rann  v.  Hughes  in 

1  **  How  far  have  the  Courts  of  Equity  gone  upon  these  principles  ?  Where  a 
man  devises  his  estate  for  payment  of  his  debts,  a  Court  of  Equity  says  (and  a  Court 
of  Lav  in  a  case  properly  before  them  would  say  the  same),  all  debts  barred  by  the 
Statute  of  Limitations  shall  come  in  and  share  the  benefit  of  the  devise  ;  because  they 
are  due  in  conscience  :  therefore  though  barred  by  law,  they  shall  be  held  to  be  revived 
and  charged  by  the  bequest.  What  was  said  in  the  argument  relative  to  the  reviving 
a  promise  at  law,  so  as  to  take  it  out  of  the  Statute  of  Limitations,  is  very  true.  The 
slightest  acknowledgment  has  been  held  sufficient,  .  .  .  So  in  the  case  of  the  man  who 
after  he  comes  of  age  promises  to  pay  for  goods  or  other  things,  which,  during  his 
minority,  one  cannot  say  he  has  contracted  for,  because  the  'aw  disables  him  from 
making  any  such  contract ;  but  which  he  has  been  fairly  and  honestly  supplied  with/' 
2  Cowper  at  p.  548. 

2  Lewis  v.  Chase  (1720)  1  P.  Wms.  620. 

3  The  judgment  begins  as  follows  :  "  Here  is  an  honest  creditor,  and  the  bankrupt 
if  he  pay  him  all,  still  pays  but  what  in  conscience  he  ought  " ;  the  decision  in  this 
case  was  contrary  to  the  spirit  of  many  other  cases,  1  P.  Wms.  622  n.  1,  and  it  was 
over-ruled  by  Sumner  v.  Brady  (1791)  1  H.  Bl.  647. 

4  Above  4-5  ;  I  shall  deal  with  the  later  history  of  consideration  in  equity  in  the 
following  Book  of  this  History ;  see  Roscoe  Pound,  Consideration  in  Equity,  Wig- 
more  Celebration  Essays  435  seqq. 

5  Roscoe  Pound,  op.  cit,  457-458.  6  (1778)  7  T.R.  350  n.  a. 


28       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

Hawkes  v.  Saunders1  (1782),  on  the  ground  that  in  the  former 
case  the  administratrix  had  no  assets.2  In  Hawkes  v.  Saunders  he 
followed  his  own  earlier  decision  in  Atkinsv.  Hill'6  (1775),  and  held 
that,  if  an  executor  had  assets  and  promised  to  pay  a  legacy, 
assumpsit  would  lie.  in  so  deciding  he  based  his  judgment  on  the 
broad  ground  that  any  moral  obligation  was  a  sufficient  considera- 
tion. "Where  a  man  is  under  a  legal  or  equitable  obligation  to 
pay,  the  law  implies  a  promise,  though  none  was  ever  actually 
made.  A  fortiori  a  legal  or  equitable  duty  is  a  sufficient  considera- 
tion for  an  actual  promise.  Where  a  man  is  under  a  moral  obligation 
which  no  court  of  law  or  equity  can  enforce,  and  promises,  the 
honesty  and  rectitude  of  the  thing  is  a  consideration."4 

It  is  true  that  in  this  judgment,  in  which  the  doctrine  that 
moral  obligation  amounts  to  consideration  attained  its  most  un- 
qualified and  complete  recognition,  we  can  see  an  echo  of  the 
reasoning  by  which  the  decision  in  S/ade's  Case5  was  justified. 
The  existence  of  a  debt  imports  a  promise,  and  so  assumpsit  will 
lie,  even  though  there  has  been  no  express  promise  to  pay.  But 
the  reasoning  appears  here  in  a  very  different  setting.  It  is  based 
wholly  on  equitable  considerations  ;  and  the  only  dictum  which 
really  supported  the  actual  decision  was  a  dictum  of  Lord  Hard- 
wicke's,  cited  by  Buller,  J.,6  to  the  effect  that  the  fact  that  assets 
had  come  to  an  executor's  hands  was  sufficient  consideration  for 
a  promise  by  him  to  pay  a  legacy.  It  is  true  that  other  cases  were 
cited  ;  but  they  bore  out  neither  the  broad  propositions  on  which 
the  judgment  was  based,  nor  the  decision  itself.  Thus  it  is  clear 
that  a  decision  that  the  indebtedness  of  a  testator  was  a  considera- 
tion for  a  promise  by  the  executor  to  pay  the  creditor,7  is  no 
authority  for  the  proposition  that  the  possession  of  assets  is  a  con- 
sideration for  a  promise  to  pay  a  legacy,  for  the  element  of  pre- 
cedent debt  is  wholly  wanting.  Nor  was  it  much  to  the  point  to 
cite  a  case  in  which  it  was  held  that  the  abandonment  of  a  right, 
enforceable  in  equity,  was  a  good  consideration.8  The  fact  that 
such  cases  could  be  cited  and  such  arguments  used,  taken  in  con- 
nection with  the  fact  that  other  older  cases,  which  pointed  in  a  very 
different  direction,  were  not  cited,9  show  that  on  the  slender  basis 

1  1  Cowper  289. 

2  "  It  is  not  like  the  case  of  Rann  v.  Hughes  ;  Tor  there  there  were  no  assets,  nor 
any  averment  of  assets  stated  in  the  declaration.  But  in  this  case  there  was  a  full 
fund ;  and  therefore  she  was  bound  in  law  justice  and  conscience  to  pay  the  plaintiff 
his  legacy,"  ibid  at  p.  291. 

3  Ibid  284.  4  Ibid  at  p.  290. 

5  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep.  92a  ;  vol.  iii  445-446. 

6  Reech  v.  Kennegal  (1748)  1  Ves.  Sen.  at  p.  126. 

7  Trewinian  v.  Howell  (1588)  Cro.  Eliza.  91,  cited  by  Buller,  J.,  1  Cowper  at 
p.  293. 

8  Wells  v.  Wells  (1669)  1  Ventris  40,  cited  by  Buller,  J.,  1  Cowper  at  p.  233. 

9  Above  11,  14-15,  18  ;  below  37-38. 


IN  XVIIITH  &  EARLY  XIXTH  CENTS.       29 

of  earlier  cases  which  allowed  that  a  precedent  debt,  though  unen- 
forceable, was  consideration  for  a  promise,  a  wholly  new  theory 
of  consideration  was  being  created.  It  is  not  surprising,  therefore 
to  find  that  any  past  decisions,  which  could  give  any  sort  of  support 
to  this  new  theory,  should  have  gained  the  approval  of  Lord 
Mansfield  and  his  colleagues.  Thus  in  the  case  of  Martyn  v. 
Hind1  he  expressed  surprise  that  anyone  could  have  doubted  the 
correctness  of  the  decision  in  Dutlon  v.  Poole  ;  -  and  in  another 
case  he  was  said  by  Buller,  J.,  to  have  expressed  the  opinion  that 
an  agreement  by  a  creditor  to  discharge  his  debtor,  in  consideration 
of  receiving  a  smaller  sum,  was  valid.3 

(ii)  The  influence  of  mercantile  law. 

Lord  Mansfield's  achievements  in  the  field  of  commercial  law 
were  remarkable  ;  and  they  were  due  largely  to  the  fact  that  he 
was  widely  read  in  other  systems  of  law  than  the  common  law. 
But  he  had  the  defects  of  his  qualities.  He  was  not  so  widely  or 
accurately  read  in  the  technical  doctrines  and  technical  history  of 
the  common  law,  as  other  lawyers  far  inferior  to  him  in  breadth  of 
intellect ;  and,  for  this  reason,  in  his  desire  to  import  reasonable 
principles  into  the  common  law,  he  was  sometimes  led  to  lay  down 
rules  which  were  demonstrably  not  rules  of  English  law.  I  have 
already  had  occasion  to  notice  this  failing  in  some  of  his  decisions 
on  points  connected  with  the  land  law.4  We  shall  now  see  that, 
in  his  desire  to  construct  a  body  of  mercantile  law  on  principles 
which  would  be  satisfactory  to  the  world  of  commerce,  he  was  led 
to  propound  a  wholly  heterodox  view  as  to  the  position  of  the 
doctrine  of  consideration  in  the  law  of  contract. 

In  1765,  in  the  case  of  Pillans  v.  Van  Mierop?  he  laid  down 
the  undoubted  principle  that  "  the  law  of  merchants  and  the  law 
of  the  land  is  the  same."  6  He  then  proceeded  to  lay  down  the 
much  more  doubtful  principle  that  "  a  nudum  pactum  does  not 
exist  in  the  usage  and  law  of  merchants."  "  But,  if  both  proposi- 
tions were  true,  a  nudum  pactum  could  not  exist  in  the  law  of 
the  land.  This  however  was  obviously  untrue,  for  an  agreement 
made  without  consideration  was  nudum  pactum,  unless  it  was 
made  in  writing  and  under  seal.  In  order  to  reconcile  the 
existence  of  this  rule  of  law  with  his  own  theory,  he  propounded 
the  view  that  consideration  was  only  of  evidentiary  value ;  and 

1  (1776)  2  Covvper  at  p.  443.  a  For  this  case  see  above  12. 

*  *•  Whether  an  agreement  by  parol  to  accept  a  smaller  sum  in  satisfaction  of  a 
larger  can  be  pleaded  or  not,  I  do  not  know  ;  it  was  formerly  considered  that  it  could 
not,  and  was  so  decided  in  Coke.  I  think  however  that  there  are  some  late  cases  to 
the  contrary,  and  one  in  particular  in  Lord  Mansfield's  time,  who  said,  that  if  a  party 
chose  to  take  a  smaller  sum,  why  should  he  not  do  it  ?  "  Stock  v.  Mawson  (1798)  1  B. 
and  P.  at  p.  290. 

4  Vol.  vii  19-20,  43-46.  5  3  Burr.  1663.  6  Ibid  at  p.  1669.  "  Ibid. 


30       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

that  therefore,  if  an  agreement  were  in  writing,  whether  under 
seal  or  not,  consideration  was  not  needed.  "  I  take  it  that  the 
ancient  notion  about  want  of  consideration  was  for  the  sake  of 
evidence  only  ;  for  when  it  is  reduced  into  writing,  as  in  covenants 
specialties  bonds  etc.,  there  was  no  objection  to  the  want  of 
consideration.  And  the  Statute  of  Frauds  proceeded  upon  the 
same  principle."  x  But  as  mercantile  contracts  are  almost  in- 
variably in  writing,  it  followed  that  "  in  commercial  cases  amongst 
merchants  the  want  of  consideration  is  not  an  objection."  2 

This  heretical  doctrine  was  very  shortly  afterwards  over-ruled 
in  the  case  of  Rami  v.  Hughes  (1778).3  The  judges,  on  being 
consulted  by  the  House  of  Lords,  laid  it  down  that  "the  law  of 
this  country  supplies  no  means  nor  affords  any  remedy  to  compel 
the  performance  of  an  agreement  made  without  sufficient  considera- 
tion ;  such  agreement  is  nudum  pactum  ex  quo  non  oritur  actio  ; 
and  whatsoever  may  be  the  sense  of  this  maxim  in  the  civil  law, 
it  is  in  the  last  mentioned  sense  only  that  it  is  to  be  understood 
in  our  law."  Hence  it  followed  that,  "  all  contracts  are,  by  the 
laws  of  England,  distinguished  into  agreements  by  specialty  and 
agreements  by  parol ;  nor  is  there  any  such  third  class  ...  as 
contracts  in  writing." 

But,  though  Lord  Mansfield's  attempt  to  make  consideration 
merely  one  of  several  kinds  of  evidence,  by  which  the  existence 
of  a  contract  could  be  proved,  failed,  his  view  that  a  merely  moral 
obligation  was  a  sufficient  consideration  grew  and  flourished.  It 
is  true  that  in  1794,  in  the  case  of  Deeks  v.  Struttf  Lord  Kenyon, 
C.J.,  in  effect  overruled  the  actual  decisions  in  Hawkes  v.  Saunders 
and  Atkins  v.  Hill,  and  held  that  no  action  at  law  could  be  main- 
tained for  a  legacy.5  But  this  decision  was  treated  as  proceeding 
on  the  ground  that  the  matter  was  not  subject  to  the  cognisance 
of  a  common  law  court,  and  not  as  in  any  way  infringing  the 
principles  laid  down  as  to  the  sufficiency  of  a  moral  obligation  to 
support  a  promise.6  We  shall  now  see  that,  though  a  reaction 
against  this  view  had  begun  to  set  in  in  the  second  quarter  of  the 

1  3  Burr,  at  p.  1669.  2  ibid. 

s  7  T.R.  350  n.  a.  *  5  T.R.  690. 

5  It  was  pointed  out  that  the  only  precedent  for  allowing  such  an  action  was  one 
in  the  time  of  the  Commonwealth ;  and  that  to  allow  individual  legatees  to  sue  would 
in  effect  overthrow  the  equitable  rules  for  the  administration  of  assets,  and  work  grave 
injustice;  thus,  "if  an  action  will  lie  for  a  legacy,  no  terms  can  be  imposed  on  the 
party  who  is  entitled  to  recover,  and  therefore  when  the  legacy  is  given  to  a  wife,  the 
husband  would  recover  at  law,  and  no  provision  could  be  made  for  the  wife  or  family  : 
whereas  a  court  of  Equity  will  take  care  to  make  some  provision  for  the  wife  in  such  a 
case,"  ibid  at  p.  692  per  Lord  Kenyon,  C.J. 

6  "  The  overturning  of  these  decisions  .  .  .  went  on  the  ground  that  the  ecclesias- 
tical court  was  the  only  legal  place  where  to  sue  for  a  legacy  .  .  .  but  the  decision  in 
Deeks  v.  Strutt  had  nothing  to  do  with  the  general  ground  of  conscience,"  Barnes  v. 
Hedley  (1809)  2  Taunt,  at  p.  191  per  Mansfield,  C.J. 


IN  XVIIITH  &  EARLY  XIXTH  CENTS.       31 

nineteenth  century,  it  was,  until  then,  almost  an  accepted  doctrine. 
In  fact,  so  deeply  did  it  leave  its  marks  on  English  law,  that 
traces  of  it  can  be  found  even  as  late  as  the  second  half  of  that 
century.1 

It  is  possible  to  trace  two  lines  of  decisions  in  which  this 
doctrine  made  its  influence  felt. 

(i)  We  have  seen  that  it  was  well  established  that  a  precedent 
debt,  though  unenforceable  by  reason  of  the  expiration  of  the 
period  fixed  by  the  statute  of  limitation,  or  infancy,  or  a  discharge 
in  bankruptcy,  was  a  valid  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise.2 
We  have  seen,  too,  that  these  decisions  were  no  very  violent 
departure  from  the  principle  that  a  precedent  debt  was  a  good 
consideration  for  a  promise  to  pay,  which  could  be  enforced  by 
indebitatus  assumpsit ;  for  in  all  these  cases  there  was  a  debt 
existing,  though  it  was  not  enforceable  by  action.3  But  these 
decisions  were  extended  to  cover  the  case  where,  by  reason  of  a 
statutory  enactment  or  of  common  law  rules,  the  contract  was 
wholly  void,  so  that  there  was  no  debt  in  existence.  Thus  in 
1 809,  in  the  case  of  Barnes  v.  Hedley?  it  was  held  that  a  promise 
to  pay  the  principal  and  legal  interest  could  be  founded  on  a 
precedent  loan,  which  was  void  by  reason  of  the  infringement  of 
the  usury  laws;  and  as  late  as  1863  this  decision  was  followed, 
in  spite  of  the  vigorous  dissent  of  Martin,  B.,  in  the  case  of  Flight 
v.  Reed}  So  too  in  18 13,  in  the  case  of  Lee  v.  Muggeridge*  a 
debt  created  by  a  bond,  which  was  void  because  it  was  given  by 
a  married  woman,  was  allowed  to  be  a  sufficient  consideration  for 
a  promise  by  her  to  pay  the  debt  after  her  husband's  death.  In 
that  case  precedents  were  cited,  which  proved  the  somewhat 
obvious  proposition  that  a  void  debt  could  not  possibly  be  a 
consideration  for  a  promise.7  But  they  were  distinguished  on 
the  ground  that,  in  those  cases  a  void  consideration  had  been 
pleaded,  and  that  they  might  have  been  decided  differently  if  the 
real  consideration — the  moral  obligation — had  been  stated.8  The 
court  then  laid  it  down  that,  "  it  has  long  been  established  that 
where  a  person  is  bound  morally  and  conscientiously  to  pay  a 
debt,  though  not  legally  bound,  a  subsequent  promise  to  pay  will 

1  See  Flight  v.  Reed  (1863)  1  H.  and  C.  703 ;  below  33. 
8  Above  26.  3  Vol.  iii  442-444  ;  above  26.  *  2  Taunt  184. 

5 1  H.  and  C.  703  ;  Martin,  BM  said  at  p.  711,  '*  I  cannot  understand  how  an  utterly 
void  and  illegal  contract  or  transaction  can  be  a  legal  consideration  for  a  new  contract." 
8  5  Taunt,  36. 

7  Barber  v.  Fox  (1670)  2  Wms.  Saunders  136;  Lloyd  v.  Lee  (1718)  1  Stra.  94. 

8  "  As  to  the  cases  of  Lloyd  v.  Lee  and  Barber  v.  Fox  they  have  been  sufficiently 
answered  by  my  Lord  and  my  brother  Chambre,  that  if  a  man  will  state  on  his 
declaration  a  consideration  which  is  no  consideration,  and  shews  no  other  consideration 
on  his  declaration,  although  another  good  consideration  may  exist,  when  that  which 
he  does  shew  fails  he  cannot  succeed  upon  the  proof  of  the  other  which  he  has  not 
alleged,"  5  Taunt,  at  p.  48  per  Gibbs,  J. 


32       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

give  a  right  of  action."  1     It  is  clear  that  no  proposition  less  wide 
would  have  sufficed  to  decide  the  case  in  favour  of  the  plaintiff. 

(ii)  We  have  seen  that  it  was  well  established  that,  if  an  act 
had  been  done  at  the  request  of  the  defendant,  this  act  was  a  valid 
consideration  for  a  promise  by  him  to  pay  for  it.2  But  we  have 
also  seen  that  this  rule  was  coming  to  be  regarded  as  resting,  not 
on  the  ground  put  forward  in  some  of  the  earlier  cases,  that  the 
act  is  in  these  circumstances  an  executed  consideration  for  the 
promise,  but  on  the  ground  that  in  such  a  case  the  law  admitted 
of  an  exception  to  the  rule  that  consideration  cannot  be  past.3  In 
the  case  of  Pillans  v.  Van  Mierop  Wilmot,  J.,  was  prepared  to  give 
a  very  wide  extension  to  this  exception.4  It  is  therefore  not  sur- 
prising to  find  that,  during  this  period,  the  rule,  established  in  this 
form,  was  extended  in  a  manner  somewhat  analogous  to  the  manner 
in  which  the  rule  that  a  precedent  debt  was  a  valid  consideration 
had  been  extended.  Just  as  the  rule  that  a  precedent  debt  was  a 
valid  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise  to  pay,  was  extended 
to  a  precedent  debt,  which  for  one  reason  or  another  was  unenforce- 
able by  action ; 5  so  the  rule  that  a  past  act  done  at  the  request  of 
the  promisor  was  a  valid  consideration  for  a  promise  to  pay,  was 
extended  to  the  case  where  a  person,  without  a  previous  request, 
voluntarily  did  what  another  was  legally  liable  to  do,  and  that 
other  in  consideration  thereof  made  a  promise.  No  doubt  this 
extension  could  be  justified  on  the  ground  that,  under  these  circum- 
stances, the  act  so  done  could  be  taken  as  executed  consideration 
for  the  subsequent  promise.  This  was  in  substance  the  explana- 
tion given  by  Selwyn ; 6  and,  as  thus  explained,  it  is  in  accord  with 
the  principles  of  the  modern  law.7  But  both  the  original  rule  and 
its  extension,  if  regarded  as  exceptions  to  the  rule  that  a  past  con- 
sideration is  not  valid,  can  easily  be  justified  by  the  theory  that  a 
moral   obligation  is  a  valid  consideration ;   for,   if  a   past  act  is 

1  5  Taunt,  at  p.  46  per  Mansfield,  C.J. 

2  Above  14-15.  3  Above  16. 

4,1  It  is  now  settled,  '  that  when  the  act  is  done  at  the  request  of  the  person 
promising,  it  will  be  a  sufficient  foundation  to  graft  the  promise  upon.'  In  another 
instance  the  strictness  has  been  relaxed ;  as  for  instance,  burying  a  son,  or  curing  a 
son ;  the  considerations  were  both  past ;  and  yet  holden  good.  It  has  been  melting 
down  into  common  sense  of  late  times,"  3  Burr,  at  pp.  1671-1672. 

8  Above  26. 

6 "The  defendants,  being  bound  by  law  to  provide  for  the  poor  of  the  parish, 
derived  a  benefit  from  the  act  of  the  plaintiff  who  afforded  that  assistance  to  the 
pauper  which  it  was  the  duty  of  the  defendants  to  have  provided :  this  was  the  con- 
sideration, and  the  subsequent  promise  by  the  defendants  to  pay  for  such  assistance 
was  evidence  from  which  it  might  be  inferred  that  the  consideration  was  performed 
by  the  plaintiff  with  the  consent  of  the  defendants,  and  consequently  sufficient  to  sup- 
port a  general  indebitatus  assumpsit  for  work  and  labour  performed  by  the  plaintiff 
for  the  defendants,  at  their  request,"  Selwyn,  Nisi  Prius  i  51  n.  11,  cited  Anson, 
Contracts  (oth  ed.)  107. 

7  Below  38-39. 


IN  XVIIITH  &  EARLY  XIXTH  CENTS.       33 

accepted  as  a  valid  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise,  it  is 
almost  tantamount  to  asserting  that  a  mere  motive  or  feeling  of 
moral  obligation  is  a  sufficient  consideration.  And  so  we  find 
that,  in  the  cases  in  which  this  extension  was  made,  moral  obliga- 
tion occupies  a  prominent  place. 

The  facts  of  all  these  cases  were  very  similar,  as  they  all  turned 
on  the  liability  of  a  parish,  in  which  a  pauper  was  settled,  to  main- 
tain him.  In  the  case  of  Atkins  v.  Banwell1  the  guardians  of  the 
parish  where  a  pauper  was  resident,  having  expended  money  on 
his  relief,  sued  the  guardians  of  the  parish  where  he  was  settled, 
to  recover  the  amount  so  expended.  It  was  held  that  the  action 
failed,  because  the  defendants  had  made  no  express  promise  to 
pay.  But  Lord  Ellenborough,  C.J.,  held  that,  if  there  had  been 
an  express  promise,  the  plaintiffs  would  have  succeeded  because 
"a  moral  obligation  is  a  good  consideration  for  an  express  pro- 
mise " ; 2  and  he  gave  effect  to  this  view  in  the  subsequent  case  of 
Wing  v.  Mill}  In  the  later  case  of  Paynter  v.  Williams 4  the 
plaintiffs,  who  had  given  relief,  recovered  against  the  parish  where 
the  pauper  was  settled,  but  on  the  ground  that  the  officers  of  the 
parish  of  settlement  had  requested  the  relief  to  be  furnished,  so 
that  it  was  a  case  of  an  act  done  at  the  request  of  the  defendant5 
Necessarily  moral  obligation  played  some  part  in  the  argument ; 6 
but  not  much  reliance  was  placed  on  it  by  either  side ;  and  we 
shall  see  that  in  1833 — the  date  when  that  case  was  decided — the 
view  that  moral  obligation  was  always  a  good  consideration  was 
beginning  to  decline."  But,  even  after  the  theory  had  ceased  to 
be  held  in  the  large  sense  given  to  it  by  Lord  Mansfield  and  by 
Mansfield,  C.J.,  traces  of  it  lingered  on  in  the  language  used  by 
distinguished  judges.  We  have  seen  that  as  late  as  1863  it  in- 
spired the  decision  of  the  court  in  Flight  v.  Reed ;  8  and  traces  of 
its  influence  can  be  seen  in  the  language  of  judgments  delivered 
by  Parke,  B.,  in  18439  and  1848.10 

1  (1802)  2  East  505.  *  2  East  at  p.  506.  i 

s  (1817)  i  B.  and  Aid.  104 — Lord  Ellenborough,  C.J.,  said,  "  in  this  case  both 
the  legal  and  moral  obligation  obtain.  The  parish  of  Willoughby  have  by  their 
weekly  allowance  admitted  that  they  were  bound  to  provide  for  the  pauper ;  and  the 
defendant,  one  of  the  overseers,  after  the  pauper's  death,  expressly  desires  the  plain- 
tiff to  send  his  bill  made  out  to  the  overseers,  and  promises  that  he  shall  be  paid." 
4  (1833)  1  C.  and  If.  810.  5  Ibid  at  pp.  818-819  per  Lord  Lyndhurst,  C.B. 

*  Ibid  at  pp.  811-818.  1  Below  37. 
•iH.  and  C.  703  ;  above  31. 

•  "  The  principle  on  which  the  law  allows  a  party,  who  has  attained  his  age  of 
twenty-one  years,  to  give  validity  to  contracts  entered  into  during  his  infancy,  is  that 
he  is  supposed  to  have  acquired  the  power  of  deciding  for  himself,  whether  the  trans- 
action in  question  is  one  of  a  meritorious  character,  by  which  in  good  conscience  he 
ought  to  be  bound,"  Williams  v.  Moor  (1843)  n  M.  and  W.  at  pp.  264-265,  and  see 
the  passage  cited  below  40  n.  1. 

M  "  The  principle  of  the  rule  laid  down  by  Lord  Mansfield  is,  that  when  the  con- 
sideration was  originally  beneficial  to  the  party'  promising,  yet  if  he  be  protected  from 
VOL.   VIII.— 3 


34       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

It  is  quite  clear  that  if  these  eighteenth-century  developments 
of  legal  doctrine  had  been  received  into  the  common  law,  the 
doctrine  of  consideration  would  not  hold  the  place  which  it  holds 
to-day  in  the  English  law  of  contract.  If  Lord  Mansfield's  view 
that  consideration  had  a  merely  evidentiary  value  had  prevailed, 
it  would  have  become  simply  one  of  several  ways  of  proving  the 
existence  of  a  contract,  it  would  have  lost  all  connection  with  its 
historical  origin  in  the  procedural  necessities  of  assumpsit,  and  it 
would  probably  have  disappeared  before  now  as  a  substantive 
body  of  doctrine.  The  acceptance  of  this  view  would,  as  Sir  F. 
Pollock  has  said,  have  changed  the  whole  modern  development  of 
the  English  law  of  contract,  "and  its  principles  might  have  been 
(with  only  minute  theoretical  differences)  assimilated  to  those  of 
the  law  of  Scotland."1  Nor  would  the  result  have  been  very 
different  if  the  theory  of  the  identification  of  moral  obligation  and 
consideration  in  its  extreme  form  had  been  accepted.  In  that  case 
the  English  theory  would  have  become  something  very  similar  to 
the  continental  theory,  which  regards  mere  moral  obligation,  or  the 
intention  to  confer  a  benefit,  as  a  sufficient  "cause."  We  shall  see 
that  this  "  cause  "  has  consequently  become  so  uncertain  a  test  for 
distinguishing  between  a  pact  and  a  contract,  that  in  the  opinion 
of  many  it  is  wholly  useless.2  And  this  is  only  natural ;  for,  as 
Lord  Denman,  C.  J.,  pointed  out  in  the  case  of  Eastwood  v.  Kenyon, 
the  doctrine  that  moral  obligation  was  a  sufficient  consideration, 
"would  annihilate  the  necessity  for  any  consideration  at  all,  inas- 
much as  the  mere  fact  of  giving  a  promise  creates  a  moral  obliga- 
tion to  perform  it."  3 

But,  as  we  shall  now  see,  these  ideas  were  decisively  rejected 
in  the  nineteenth  century,  the  procedural  origin  of  the  doctrine 
of  consideration  was  recalled,  and  the  modern  law  was  settled  on 
this  basis. 

The  Settlement  of  the  Modern  Doctrine 

The  causes  which  brought  about  the  rejection  of  theories, 
which  seemed  to  have  acquired  so  much  authority  in  the 
eighteenth    century,    must    be    sought    ultimately   in  weight   of 

liability  by  some  provision  of  the  statute  or  common  law,  meant  for  his  advantage,  he 
may  renounce  the  benefit  of  that  law  ;  and  if  he  promises  to  pay  the  debt,  which  is 
only  what  an  honest  man  ought  to  do,  he  is  then  bound  by  the  law  to  perform  it," 
Earle  v.  Oliver  (1848)  2  Ex.  at  p.  90. 

1"  If  it  had  occurred  a  century  or  two  earlier  to  a  judge  of  anything  like  Lord 
Mansfield's  authority,  the  whole  modern  development  of  the  English  law  of  contract 
might  have  been  changed,  and  its  principles  might  have  been  (with  only  minute 
theoretical  differences)  assimilated  to  those  of  the  law  of  Scotland,"  Contracts  (9th 
ed.)  191 ;  the  only  criticism  that  can  be  made  of  this  dictum  is  that  it  probably  could 
not  have  occurred  to  any  judge  "  a  century  or  two  earlier,"  as  the  procedural  origin  of 
consideration  was  then  too  well  recognized. 

8  Below  44.  3(i84o)  11  Ad.  and^E.  at  p.  450. 


SETTLEMENT  OF  MODERN  DOCTRINE     35 

earlier  precedents,  which  came  from  a  period  when  the  origin  of 
consideration,  in  the  procedural  necessities  of  assumpsit  and  to 
some  extent  of  debt,  was  almost  too  obvious  to  require  state- 
ment. We  must  therefore  examine  the  manner  in  which  these 
precedents  were  used  to  prove  that  consideration  was  something 
very  much  more  than  mere  evidence,  and  more  than  motive  or 
moral  obligation. 

It  was  the  view  expressed  by  Lord  Mansfield  in  Pillans  v. 
Van  Mierop}  that  consideration  was  merely  evidence  of  the 
existence  of  the  contract,  that  was  the  first  to  be  rejected.  It 
was,  as  we  have  seen,  rejected  in  the  case  of  Rann  v.  Hughes'1 
only  thirteen  years  later,  so  that  it  had  no  time  to  gather  weight 
by  the  approval  express  or  tacit  of  later  judges.  That  it  was  so 
speedily  rejected  is,  in  my  opinion,  an  indirect  and  undesigned 
consequence  of  §  4  of  the  statute  of  Frauds.  The  case  of  Rann 
v.  Hughes  was  an  action  on  a  promise  by  an  administratrix  to 
pay  out  of  her  own  estate.3  It  was  urged  that,  as  the  statute  had 
required  such  promises  to  be  in  writing,  they  did  not  require 
consideration  to  support  them.  But  it  was  clear  enough,  both 
from  the  words  of  the  statute  and  from  the  manner  in  which  it 
had  been  interpreted,  that  non-observance  of  the  provisions  of 
the  statute  rendered  the  contract,  not  void,  but  unenforceable  by 
action.4  If  this  had  not  been  so,  it  would  have  been  impossible 
for  equity  to  have  originated  the  equitable  doctrine  of  part 
performance,  the  beginnings  of  which  we  can  see  in  the  time  of 
Lord  North,5  who  had  helped  to  draft  the  statute ; 6  nor  would  it 
have  been  possible  for  a  contract  to  be  proved  by  means  of  a 
written  memorandum  drawn  up  after  the  agreement  had  been 
made.7  It  was  the  better  opinion,  therefore,  that  writing  affected, 
not  the  validity,  but  the  enforceability  of  the  contract. 8     It  followed 

1  (J765)  3  Burr-  at  p.  1669  ;  above  29-30.  2(i778)  7  T.R.  350  n.  a. 

3  It  is  not  even  certain  that  the  promise  was  in  that  case  in  writing — "  It  is  said 
that  if  this  promise  is  in  writing  that  takes  away  the  necessity  of  a  consideration, 
and  obviates  the  objection  of  nudum  pactum,  for  that  cannot  be  where  the  promise 
is  put  in  writing :  and  that  after  verdict,  if  it  were  necessary  to  support  the 
promise  that  it  should  be  in  writing,  it  will  after  verdict  be  presumed  that  it  was  in 
writing;  and  this  last  is  certainly  true,"  7  T.R.  350  n.  a. 

*  "  It  was  said  by  the  Attorney-General,  that  since  the  statute  of  Frauds,  if  an 
agreement  be  made  and  reduced  into  writing,  and  signed  but  not  sealed,  that  this  is 
still  but  a  parol  agreement,  and  the  writing  is  only  evidence  of  it,"  Marquis  of 
Normanby  v.  Duke  of  Devonshire  (1697)  Free.  Ch.  at  p.  217. 

5  Hollis  v.  Edwards  (1683)  1  Vern.  159 ;  Butcher  v.  Stapely  (1685)  1  Vera. 
363  ;  vol.  vi  658-659. 

8  Vol.  vi  380-384. 

7  Smith  v.  Watson  (1719)  Bunbury  55  ;  cp.  Welford  v.  Beazely  (1747)  3  Atk. 
5<M- 

8  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  699-701 ;  the  discussion  in  Leroux  v.  Brown 
(1852)  12  C.B.  801,  in  which  the  rule  was  finally  decided,  was  confused  by  refer- 
ences to  the  question  cf  the  effect  of  §  17  of  the  statute ;  that  section  was  differently 
worded,  and  no  final  decision  was  reached  as  to  its  effect,  vol.  vi  386  n.  4. 


36       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

that,  if  consideration  was  needed  for  the  validity  of  all  contracts 
not  under  seal,  it  must  be  necessary  for  contracts  required  to  be 
in  writing  by  the  statute  of  Frauds.  But  for  the  fact  that  the 
contract  then  before  the  court  was  one  which  fell  within  the  fourth 
section  of  the  statute,  and  but  for  the  fact  that  the  statute  affected 
only  the  enforceability  of  such  contracts,  it  may  well  be  doubted 
whether  Lord  Mansfield's  opinion,  which  is  not  in  itself  unreason- 
able, would  have  been  so  speedily  and  decisively  overruled.  If 
it  had  not  been  speedily  overruled,  and  if  it  had  been  combined 
with  the  doctrine  that  moral  obligation  was  equivalent  to  con- 
sideration, very  little  would,  as  we  have  seen,  have  been  left  of 
the  doctrine  of  consideration. 

Though  the  case  of  Rann  v.  Hughes  did  not  allude  to  the 
doctrine  of  moral  obligation,  though,  as  we  have  seen,  that 
doctrine  continued  to  flourish  for  many  years  after  that  decision,1 
the  opening  words  of  the  judgment  impliedly  condemn  the  wide 
meaning  afterwards  given  to  it  by  Mansfield,  C.J.  "  It  is  un- 
doubtedly true,"  said  Skynner,  C.B.,  in  the  name  of  the  judges,2 
"that  every  man  is  by  the  law  of  nature  bound  to  fulfil  his 
engagements.  It  is  equally  true  that  the  law  of  this  country 
supplies  no  means,  nor  affords  any  remedy,  to  compel  the  per- 
formance of  an  agreement  made  without  sufficient  consideration." 
There  were  many  lawyers  who  saw  clearly  enough  that  the  large 
efficacy  attributed  to  moral  obligation  could  not  be  supported. 
Coke's  doctrine  that  consideration  "must  be  either  an  immediate 
benefit  to  the  party  promising  or  a  loss  to  the  person  to  whom  the 
promise  was  made," 3  was  still  put  forward  in  argument.  And, 
though  this  doctrine  was  then  denounced  as  too  narrow,4  it  still 
had  life  in  it.  In  1802  the  reporters  Bosanquet  and  Puller 
appended  to  their  report  of  the  case  of  Wennall  v.  Adney  a 
learned  note,  which  showed  that  the  doctrine  that  moral  obligation 
was  a  sufficient  consideration  to  support  a  promise,  was  inconsistent 
with  the  earlier  authorities,  and  was  unnecessary  for  the  decision 
of  most  of  the  cases  usually  cited  for  it.5  They  maintained  that 
"if  a  contract  between  two  persons  be  void,  and  not  merely 
voidable,  no  subsequent  express  promise  will  operate  to  charge 
the  party  promising,  even  though  he  has  derived  the  benefit  of 
the  contract";  though  they  admitted  that,  "according  to  the  com- 

1  Above  30-31.  2  7  T.R.  350  n.  a. 

3  Stone  v.  Wythipol  (1588)  Cro.  Eliza,  at  p.  126,  cited  above  10  and  n.  8. 

*  "  The  rule  laid  down  at  the  Bar,  as  to  what  is  or  is  not  a  good  consideration 
in  law,  goes  upon  a  very  narrow  ground  indeed ;  namely,  that  to  make  a  considera- 
tion to  support  an  assumpsit,  there  must  be  either  an  immediate  benefit  to  the  party 
promising,  or  a  loss  to  the  person  to  whom  the  promise  was  made.  I  cannot  agree 
to  that  being  the  only  ground  of  consideration  sufficient  to  raise  an  assumpsit," 
Hawkes  v.  Saunders  (1782)  1  Cowper  at  p.  290  per  Lord  Mansfield,  C.J. 

5  3  B.  and  P.  249. 


SETTLEMENT  OF  MODERN  DOCTRINE      37 

monly  received  notion  respecting  moral  obligations,  and  the  force  at- 
tributed to  a  subsequent  express  promise,  such  a  person  ought  to 
pay."  They  maintained  that  "  an  express  promise  can  only  revive 
a  precedent  good  consideration,  which  might  have  been  enforced 
at  law  through  the  medium  of  an  implied  promise,  had  it  not  been 
suspended  by  a  positive  rule  of  law,  but  can  give  no  original  right 
of  action,  if  the  obligation  on  which  it  is  founded  never  could  have 
been  enforced  at  law."  In  other  words,  a  precedent  debt,  as 
decided  in  Slack's  Case}  is  a  valid  consideration  on  which  indebi- 
tatus assumpsit  will  lie,  either  by  reason  of  a  subsequent  express 
promise,  or,  if  no  subsequent  promise  has  been  made,  by  reason 
of  the  promise  implied  from  the  debt;  and  a  precedent  debt, 
though  voidable  or  unenforceable  by  action,  is  a  good  consideration 
for  a  subsequent  express  promise  to  pay.  But  a  precedent  void 
obligation,  because  it  is  void,  cannot  be  a  consideration,  whatever 
be  the  moral  obligation  which  arises  from  its  creation. 

That  this  note  had  much  to  do  with  the  change  of  opinion  on 
this  subject,  which  took  place  in  the  latter  part  of  the  nineteenth 
century,  is  clear  from  the  use  made  of  it  in  later  cases.  It  was 
used  in  argument  in  the  case  of  Paynter  v.  Williams}'  it  was 
approved  by  Parke,  B.,  in  Earle  v.  Oliver}  and  it  was  cited,  though 
it  was  misapplied  by  Pollock,  C.B.,  and  Wilde,  B.,  in  Flight  v. 
Reed}  More  important  than  all,  it  was  approved  by  Denman,  C.  J., 
in  the  case  of  Eastwood  v.  Kenyon* — the  case  which  gave  the 
death  blow  to  the  theory  that  moral  obligation  could  be  regarded 
as  a  valid  consideration.  Lord  Denman's  opinions  upon  this 
question  had  progressed.  In  18386  he  had  contented  himself 
with  following  in  substance  a  decision  of  Lord  Tenterden's  in  1 83 1,7 
and  holding  that  the  plaintiff  failed,  because,  if  there  was  a  moral 
obligation,  it  had  not  been  sufficiently  set  forth  in  the  declaration. 
But  in  Eastwood  v.  Kenyon  he  stated  clearly  that  moral  obligation 
could  never  be  a  consideration ;  and  it  is  clear  that  the  decision 
was  mainly  grounded,  as  the  note  to  Wennall  v.  Adney  was 
grounded,  upon  the  "old  common  law  of  England,"  contained  in 
such  cases  as  Hunt  v.  Bate,  Townsend  v.  Hunt,  "and  indeed  in 

1  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep,  92a.  3  (1833)  1  C.  and  M.  at  p.  816. 

3(i84fc)  2  Ex.  at  p.  90.  4(i863)  i  H.  and  C.  at  p.  716. 

5  (1840)  11  Ad.  and  E.  at  p.  447. 

8  Meyer  v.  Haworth  8  Ad.  and  E.  467 ;  at  p.  469  Lord  Denman,  C.J.,  said,  "  the 
record  states  that  the  goods  were  supplied  to  a  married  woman,  who,  after  her 
husband's  death,  promised  to  pay.  That  is  not  sufficient.  The  debt  was  never  owing 
from  her.     If  there  was  a  moral  obligation  that  should  have  been  shown." 

7Littlefield  v.  Shee  2  B.  and  Ad.  811 ;  Lord  Tenterden,  C.J.,  observed  at  p.  812 
that,  in  Lee  v.  Muggeridge,  all  the  circumstances  showing  that  the  money  "was  in 
conscience  due"  were  set  forth  in  the  declaration  ;  but  it  should  be  noted  that  he  felt 
misgivings  as  to  the  extent  of  the  doctrine — "  the  doctrine  that  a  moral  obligation  is  a 
sufficient  consideration  for  a  subsequent  promise  is  one  which  should  be  received  with 
some  limitation." 


38      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

numerous  old  books."1  "The  principle,"  he  said,  "of  moral 
obligation  does  not  make  its  appearance  till  the  days  of  Lord 
Mansfield,  and  then  under  circumstances  not  inconsistent  with  this 
ancient  doctrine  when  properly  explained."  From  that  time 
onwards  the  doctrine  of  consideration  has  been  developed  for  the 
most  part  on  strictly  historical  lines,  and  entirely  in  accordance 
with  those  older  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  century  precedents, 
which  regarded  the  term  consideration  as  the  compendious  word 
which  summed  up  the  conditions  which  a  plaintiff  must  satisfy 
before  he  could  succeed  in  indebitatus  or  in  special  assumpsit. 

Though  this  note  to  Wennall  v.  Adney  had  much  to  do  with 
producing  this  change  of  opinion,  it  is  possible  that  it  was  partly 
due  to  the  new  rules  of  pleading  which  were  made  in  1834.  We 
shall  see  that  those  rules  prevented  defendants  from  pleading  the 
general  issue  in  assumpsit,  and  required  them  to  plead  specially.2 
This  change  obviously  tended  to  concentrate  attention  upon  the 
kind  of  pleas  appropriate  to  the  action,  and  to  call  increased 
attention  to  the  procedural  basis  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration. 
However  that  may  be,  the  fact  of  this  change  in  the  attitude  of 
the  courts  is  undoubted.  It  is  a  change  in  attitude  which  is 
analogous  to  that  already  noted  in  the  view  taken  by  them  as  to 
the  extent  of  the  modification  of  the  maxim  actio  personalis  nioritur 
cum  persona  recognized  in  the  case  of  Phillips  v.  Homfray  ;z  and 
as  to  the  relations  of  the  actions  of  trover  and  trespass  de  bonis 
asportatis.4     As  we  shall  now  see,  it  has  made  our  modern  law. 

Three  consequences  followed  from  the  decision  in  Eastwood  v. 
Kenyon  that  a  past  consideration  was  no  valid  consideration,  and 
that  moral  obligation  was  not  the  same  thing  as  consideration.  In 
the  first  place,  it  became  possible  to  distinguish  clearly  between 
motive  and  consideration.  This  distinction  was  stated  in  its  final 
form  two  years  later  in  the  case  of  Thomas  v.  Thomas?  In  the 
second  place,  it  became  possible  to  get  rid  of  the  confusion  caused 
by  the  habit  of  regarding  a  consideration  executed  on  request,  as 
an  exception  to  the  rule  that  a  past  consideration  is  invalid.  In 
truth,  as  had  long  ago  been  pointed  out  by  Selwyn,  in  connection 
with  the  cases  turning  on  the  liability  of  the  poor  law  authorities,6 
those  cases  could  be  treated  more  properly  as  cases  of  executed 
consideration.      It  is  clear,  as  we  have  seen  from  Lampleigh  v. 

1 11  Ad.  and  E.  at  p.  452 ;  for  the  cases  cited  see  above  14-15. 

2  Vol.  ix  c.  7  §  2 ;  Common  Law  Procedure  Commission,  First  Report,  Park 
Papers  (1831)  xxii  at  pp.  590,  599  ;  Cambridge  Law  Journal  i  273-275. 

3  Vol.  iii  582.  4  Vol.  vii  420-421. 

6 (1842)  2  Q.B.  851;  "motive  is  not  the  same  thing  with  consideration.  Con- 
sideration means  something  which  is  of  some  value  in  the  eye  of  the  law  moving  from 
the  plaintiff,"  ibid  at  p.  859  per  Patteson,  J. 

6  Above  32  n.  6. 


SETTLEMENT  OF  MODERN  DOCTRINE      39 

Brathwait l  and  numerous  other  cases  before  and  after  that  decision,2 
that  the  validity  of  a  consideration  executed  on  request  is  not  an 
exception  to  the  rule  that  a  past  consideration  is  invalid,  but  simply 
a  case  of  an  executed  consideration.  This  new  point  of  view  can 
be  seen  gradually  emerging  in  the  decisions  of  the  latter  half  of  the 
nineteenth  century ; 3  and  it  received  its  clearest  statement  from 
Bowen,  L.J.,  in  Stewart  v.  Casey*1 — "The  fact  of  a  past  service 
raises  an  implication  that  at  the  time  it  was  rendered  it  was  to  be 
paid  for ;  and,  if  it  was  a  service  which  was  to  be  paid  for,  when 
you  get  in  the  subsequent  document  a  promise  to  pay,  that  promise 
may  be  treated  either  as  an  admission  which  evidences,  or  as  a 
positive  bargain  which  fixes,  the  amount  of  that  reasonable  re- 
muneration on  the  faith  of  which  the  service  was  originally 
rendered."  Thus  most  of  the  so-called  exceptions  to  the  rule  that 
consideration  cannot  be  past  disappear.5  It  is  true  that  the  rule  is 
still  recognized  that  a  precedent  debt,  though  barred  by  the  statute 
of  limitation,  is  consideration  for  a  promise  to  pay,  or  for  an 
acknowledgment  from  which  a  promise  to  pay  can  be  inferred. 
But  it  is  not  a  consideration  for  a  promise  to  do  any  other  collateral 
thing;6  for,  as  Lord  Sumner  has  pointed  out  in  his  learned  judg- 
ment in  the  case  of  Spencer  v.  Hemmerde,  the  rule  only  applied  to 
actions  of  assumpsit  for  debts,  and  not  to  actions  for  other  kinds 
of  damage.8  Thus,  though  the  consideration  is  in  this  case  past,  it 
is  a  legitimate  extension  of  the  rule  that  a  precedent  debt  would 
support  an  action  of  indebitatus  assumpsit7  And  this  is  the  true 
historical  ground.  But  at  the  present  day,  when  the  procedural 
origin  of  this  anomalous  rule  has  been  forgotten,  it  is  perhaps 
better  to  base  it,  as  Holt,  C.J.,9  and  Sir  F.  Pollock  have  based  it,10 

1  (1614)  Hobart  105  ;  above  15.  a  Above  14-16. 

3Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  114-116. 

4  [1892]  1  Ch.  at  pp.  115- 116.  It  is  unfortunate  that  Scrutton,  L.J.,  in  Evans  v. 
Heathcote  [1918]  1  K.B.  at  pp.  435-436,  persisted  in  the  old  error  of  regarding  the 
consideration  in  Lampleigh  v.  Brathwait  as  past,  and  even  referred  to  the  decision  in 
Flight  v.  Reed  without  positive  disapproval. 

5  Changes  in  statute  law  have  changed  the  rules  that  the  infant's  promise,  after  he 
has  attained  his  majority,  to  pay  a  debt  contracted  during  infancy,  and  the  bankrupt's 
promise  after  getting  his  discharge  to  pay  a  debt  formerly  owing  by  him,  are  valid, 
Anson,  Contracts  (7th  ed.)  102. 

•  "  But  it  does  not  follow  that,  though  a  promise  revives  a  debt  in  such  cases,  any 
of  those  debts  will  be  a  sufficient  consideration  to  support  a  promise  to  do  a  collateral 
thing,  as  to  supply  goods,  or  perform  work  and  labour  ;  and  so  indeed  it  was  held  in 
this  court  in  the  case  of  Reeves  v.  Hearne  (1  M.  and  W.  323).  In  such  a  case  it  is  but 
an  accord  unexecuted,  and  no  action  will  he  for  not  executing  it,"  Earle  v.  Oliver  (1848) 
2  Ex.  at  p.  90. 

7  Vol.  iii  442-444  ;  above  9. 

8  [1922]  2  A.C.  at  p.  524  ;  see  L.Q.R.  xxxix  146-148. 

9  Heyling  v.  Hastings  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  421 ;  in  Tanner  v.  Smart  (1827) 
6  B.  and  C.  at  pp.  607-608  it  was  said  that  the  pleadings  were  not  calculated  to  raise 
the  question  of  waiver,  and  the  point  was  passed  over. 

10  "  It  seems  better  at  this  day  to  say  that  the  law  of  limitation  does  not  belong  to 
substantive  law  at  all,  but  is  a  special  rule  of  procedure  made  in  favour  of  the  debtor, 
who  may  waive  its  protection  if  he  deliberately  chooses  to  do  so,"  Contracts  (9th  ed.) 
193. 


40      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

on  the  ground  that  the  defendant  has  waived  the  benefit  of  the 
statute.1  In  the  third  place,  this  decision  emphasized  the  rule 
that  consideration  must  move  from  the  promisee,  and  so  got  rid  of 
cases  like  Dutton  v.  Poole?  where  the  judges  had  evidently  been 
influenced  by  the  equitable  doctrine  of  consideration.3  That  rule 
had  been  strongly  asserted  in  1833,  in  the  case  of  Price  v.  Easton  ; 4 
and  in  1 861,  in  the  case  of  Tweddle  v.  Atkinson,  it  was  finally 
held  that  "  the  modern  cases  had  in  effect  overruled  the  old 
decisions";  and  that  they  "shewed  that  the  consideration  must 
move  from  the  party  entitled  to  sue  upon  the  contract."  5 

It  is  by  the  application  of  the  same  principles  that  other 
doubtful  points  in  the  law  of  consideration  have  been  practically 
settled.  Thus  the  case  of  Foakes  v.  Beer6  settled  that  the  payment 
of  a  smaller  sum  by  a  debtor  to  a  creditor,  to  whom  a  larger  sum 
is  due,  is  not  a  valid  consideration  for  a  promise  by  the  creditor  to 
release  his  debtor.  In  such  a  case,  said  Lord  Selborne,7  "  I  can- 
not say  that  I  think  that  consideration  is  given  in  the  sense  in 
which  I  have  always  understood  that  word  as  used  in  our  law." 
On  somewhat  similar  grounds  it  may  be  doubted  whether  A's 
performance  of  his  contractual  duty  to  B  can  be  consideration  for 
a  promise  by  C  to  A.  Here  A  has  only  done  what  he  was  legally 
bound  to  do,  just  as  when  he  pays  part  of  his  debt  to  B.  In 
neither  case  is  there  any  detriment  to  A,  the  promisee,  which  can 
afford  a  consideration  for  a  further  promise.8 

Whether  or  not  a  promise  by  a  debtor  A  to  pay  less  than  his 
debt  to  his  creditor  B,  can  be  a  consideration  for  a  promise  by  B 
to  release  him  is  more  doubtful.  There  is  much  authority  to  show 
that  an  accord  to  be  operative  must  always  be  executed  ;  and,  as 
we  have  seen,  actual  performance  of  less  than  is  due  is  not  a  con- 

1  The  rationale  of  the  analogous  case  of  a  promise  given  by  an  infant,  after  attain- 
ing his  majority,  was  never  clearly  settled ;  in  Williams  v.  Moor  (1843)  11  M.  and  W. 
at  p.  263,  Parke,  B.,  said  that  it  might  be  treated,  either  "  as  an  act  giving  validity  to  an 
otherwise  invalid  contract,  or  as  a  new  contract,  voluntarily  entered  into  after  the  party 
has  obtained  the  capacity  of  contracting,  the  consideration  being  the  moral  duty  arising 
from  the  previous  transactions." 

2  (1677)  2  Lev.  2ii.  3  Above  12.  44  B.  and  Ad.  433. 
5 1  B.  and  S.  393.                      6  (1884)  g  A.C.  605.  7  At  p.  613. 

8  "  Andrew's  performance  of  his  binding  promise  to  Peter  does  not  appear  capable 
of  being  a  consideration  for  a  new  promise  by  John  to  Andrew  ;  not  because  it  cannot 
be  beneficial  to  John,  for  this  it  may  very  well  be,  but  because  in  contemplation  of  law 
the  performance  is  no  new  detriment  to  Andrew,  but  on  the  contrary  is  beneficial  to 
him,  inasmuch  as  it  discharges  him  of  an  existing  obligation.  Therefore  the  necessary 
element  of  detriment  to  the  promisee  is  wanting.  It  seems  therefore  that  if  a  promise 
is  given  in  exchange  merely  for  the  performance  of  the  promisee's  duty  under  an 
existing  contract  with  a  third  person,  it  is  not  binding,"  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.) 
198,  L.Q.R.  xvii  419-420;  Sir  F.  Pollock  adds,  however,  that  "  authority  is  the  other 
way  so  far  as  it  goes,"  citing  Bagge  v.  Slade,  Scotson  v.  Pegg,  and  Shadwell  v. 
Shadwell ;  but  the  first  two  cases  may  be  perhaps  regarded  as  cases  where  a  promise 
was  given  for  a  promise,  above  23-24  below  41  ;  and  in  the  last  case  it  may  perhaps 
be  contended  that  the  point  did  not  arise,  as  the  promisee  did  more  than  he  was  bound 
to  do  under  his  contract,  below  41. 


SETTLEMENT  OF  MODERN  DOCTRINE      41 

sideration.  On  the  other  hand,  the  better  opinion  would  seem 
to  be  that  a  promise  by  A  to  C  to  perform  his  contractual 
duty  to  B  may  be  consideration  for  a  promise  by  C  to  A.  It  is  a 
case  of  promise  for  promise ;  and  no  exceptional  rule,  excluding 
this  particular  kind  of  promise  from  the  general  rule  that  mutual 
promises  are  a  valid  consideration  for  each  other,  can,  as  Sir  F. 
Pollock  has  pointed  out,  be  produced.1  In  this  respect  it  differs 
from  a  promise  by  a  debtor  to  his  creditor  to  pay  a  less  sum  than 
his  debt  in  consideration  for  a  promise  of  discharge ;  for  there  is,  as 
we  shall  see,2  some  authority  for  saying  that  an  exceptional  rule 
exists  which  prevents  these  promises  from  being  consideration  for 
one  another.  In  fact  two  cases — Shadwell  v.  Shadwell z  and 
Scotson  v.  Pegg* — are  in  favour  of  the  validity  of  the  former  class 
of  contracts.     But  both  of  these  cases  call  for  some  comment 

The  case  of  Shadwell  v.  Shadwell 'did  not  necessarily  involve  the 
decision  of  this  point  In  that  case  an  uncle  promised  his  nephew, 
who  was  engaged  to  be  married,  that  he  would  on  his  nephew's 
marriage  pay  him  ^150  a  year.  Obviously  the  nephew,  though 
bound  to  marry  the  lady  at  some  time,  was  not  bound  to  marry 
her  immediately.  Relying  on  his  uncle's  promise  he  did  what  he 
was  not  bound  to  do — he  married  her  immediately.  This,  as  Erie, 
C.J.,  pointed  out,  was  an  ample  consideration.5  The  case  of 
Scotson  v.  Pegg  did  involve  the  determination  of  this  point ;  and 
though  Martin,  B.,  and  to  some  extend  Wilde,  B.,  based  their  judg- 
ments on  the  erroneous  view  that  "any  act  done  whereby  the 
contracting  party  receives  a  benefit  is  a  good  consideration  for  a 
promise  by  him,"6  the  principle  which  we  are  discussing  was 
correctly  stated  by  Wilde,  B.  "  I  accede,"  he  said,  "to  the  pro- 
position that  if  a  person  contracts  with  another  to  do  a  certain 
thing,  he  cannot  make  the  performance  of  it  a  consideration  for  a 
new  promise  to  the  same  individual.  But  there  is  no  authority  for 
the  proposition  that,  where  there  has  been  a  promise  to  one  person 
to  do  a  certain  thing,  it  is  not  possible  to  make  a  valid  promise 
to  another  to  do  the  same  thing."  7 

1  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  200-201.  2  Below  83-85. 

3(iS6o)  9  C.B.N.S.  159.  4(i86o)  6  H.  and  N.  295. 

••'  The  plaintiff  may  have  made  a  most  material  change  in  his  position,  and  in- 
duced the  object  of  his  affection  to  do  the  same,  and  may  have  incurred  pecuniary 
liabilities  resulting  in  embarrassments,  «  hich  would  be  in  every  sense  a  lo;s,  if  the 
income  which  had  been  promised  should  be  withheld  ;  and,  if  the  promise  was  made 
in  order  to  induce  the  parties  to  marry,  the  promise  so  made  would  be  in  legal  effect 
a  request  to  marry,"  9  C.B.N.S.  at  p.  174. 

•  6  H.  and  N.  at  p.  299  ;  Wilde,  B.,  said  at  p.  300,  "  but  why  is  there  no  considera- 
tion ?  It  is  said  because  the  plaintiffs  in  delivering  the  coals,  are  only  performing 
that  which  they  were  already  bound  to  do.  But  to  say  that  there  is  no  consideration 
is  to  say  that  it  is  not  possible  for  one  man  to  have  an  interest  in  the  performance  of  a 
contract  made  by  another." 

7  Ibid  at  pp.  300-301. 


42      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

Thus  the  modern  doctrine  of  consideration  was  settled  on  lines, 
which  are  remarkable  for  the  historical  and  logical  correctness  with 
which  they  have  been  deduced  from  that  procedural  basis  in  the 
action  of  assumpsit,  from  which  the  conception  of  consideration 
originated.  Whether  the  resulting  law  is  wholly  fit  for  the  needs 
of  this  twentieth  century  is  another  question,  which  I  shall  discuss 
in  the  following  section. 

"Cause"  and  Consideration^ 

We  have  seen  that  the  canon  law,  starting  from  the  basis  that 
faith  should  be  kept,  had  evolved  a  theory  of  contract  based  upon 
a  generalized  conception  of  the  Roman  causa ;  and  that  this 
canonist  conception  of  causa  has  been  accepted  and  applied  by 
the  chancellors  in  the  exercise  of  the  jurisdiction  which,  during 
the  Middle  Ages,  they  were  assuming  over  contract.2  This  fact 
comes  out  clearly  enough  in  the  Latin  version  of  the  Doctor  and 
Student;3  and  that  the  Doctor  and  Student  correctly  represented 
the  facts  may  be  said  to  have  been  proved  by  Barbour's  essay  on 
the  history  of  contract  in  early  English  equity.4  I  have  already 
described  the  main  characteristics  of  this  conception  of  causa ; 
and  at  this  point  it  is  only  necessary  to  recall  briefly  its  main 
characteristics.  They  may  be  summed  up,  says  Sir  Paul  Vino- 
gradoff,  under  the  following  heads  :5  "(i)  The  promise  must  be 
intentional ;  (2)  it  is  subject  to  be  taken  back  in  consequence  of  a 
material  change  of  circumstances ;  (3)  it  must  have  a  reasonable 
cause,  which  may  consist  either  in  a  material  equivalent  or  in  moral 
considerations  ;  (4)  a  liberal  disposition  is  to  be  deemed  a  sufficient 
cause  in  the  case  of  gifts;  (5)  promises  to  moral  persons,  to 
political  learned  or  religious  bodies,  are  legally  valid  if  they  are 
made  for  the  sake  of  their  moral  aims,  e.g.  for  the  honour  of  God, 
the  advancement  of  learning,  assistance  of  the  poor,  and  the  like." 

It  is  obvious  that  this  canonist  theory  of  causa  made  for  an 
extension  of  the  sphere  of  the  enforceable  agreement,  and  a  cor- 
responding restriction  of  the  sphere  of  the  nude  pact ;  for  if,  as 
seems  probable,  causa  in  the  civil  law  means  actionability,6  the 
extended  meaning  given  to  the  term  by  the  canonists  necessarily 
had  this  effect.  In  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  the 
tendency  towards  this  extension  was  assisted  by  two  other  causes. 

1  On  this  subject  see  E.  G.  Lorenzen,  Causa  and  Consideration  in  the  Law  of  Con- 
tracts, Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  621 ;  and  a  paper  by  F.  P.  Walton,  L.Q.R.  xli  306. 

2  Vol.  v  294-296.  3  L.Q.R.  xxiv  381-384  ;  vol.  v.  267. 

4  Ibid  263,  294.  5  L.Q.R.  xxiv  382  ;  cp.  vol.  iii  412  ;  vol.  v.  294-295. 

6  "  With  the  Romans  an  agreement  was  not  actionable  unless  there  was  some 
reason  why  it  should  be  so.  The  result  is  that,  in  these  texts,  causa  means  action- 
ability, and  does  not  denote  anything  else,  independent  of  actionability,  which  creates 
that  important  characteristic,"  Buckland,  Roman  Private  Law  232. 


«  CAUSE  "  AND  CONSIDERATION       43 

It  was  assisted,  firstly,  by  the  notion  that  "  the  enforceable  quality 
of  all  agreements  was  demanded  by  natural  law,  and  that  the 
non-enforceability  of  pacts  was  a  specific  Roman  doctrine  which 
was  opposed  to  natural  law " ;  *  and,  secondly,  by  the  mistaken 
idea  that  the  old  Germanic  law  specially  emphasized  the  duty  of 
keeping  faith.2  These  two  causes,  and  especially  the  second, 
led  in  Germany  to  the  total  elimination  of  causa  as  a  necessary 
condition  precedent  for  the  enforceability  of  contracts.3  In  other 
countries,  however,  a  causa  still  continued  to  be  necessary ;  but  it 
was  a  causa  of  the  canonist  type.  It  would  seem,  in  fact,  that  this 
canonist  theory  of  causa  inspired  the  theory  of  contract  accepted 
in  many  continental  states  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth 
centuries.4  Thus  the  necessity  for  a  causa  is  stated  to  be  necessary 
by  many  writers  on  Roman-Dutch  law.5  It  was  introduced  into 
the  French  law  by  Domat,  accepted  by  Pothier,  and,  through 
Pothier,  found  a  place  in  the  code  Napoleon.6  Brissaud  points 
out  that  the  theory  was  accepted  the  more  easily,  because  it  could 
be  regarded  as  a  development  of  the  older  ideas  which  required 
something  which  corresponded  to  the  English  quid  pro  quo.7 

But  the  "  cause,"  which  was  thus  adopted  into  French  law 
and  Roman-Dutch  law,  was,  as  might  be  expected  from  the  con- 
ditions under  which  it  originated,  both  elastic  and  vague.  Thus, 
"  the  existence  of  a  natural,  i.e.  moral  obligation,  or  even  of  a  real 
or  supposed  duty  in  point  of  honour  only,  may  be  quite  enough. 
Nay,  the  deliberate  intention  of  conferring  a  gratuitous  benefit, 
where  such  intention  exists,  is  a  sufficient  foundation  for  a  binding 
unilateral  promise."  8     It  is  not  surprising,  therefore,  that  consider- 

1  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  631.  2  Ibid. 

*  "  In  Germany  the  notion  erroneously  attributed  to  the  older  Germanic  law  that 
4  every  lawful  agreement  entered  into  with  the  serious  intention  of  being  legally  bind- 
ing would  directly  produce  of  its  own  force  obligatory  effect,  without  regard  to  the 
form  in  which  it  was  expressed,'  ultimately  prevailed  ;  which  left  no  room  for  the 
requirement  of  a  causa  as  a  necessary  element  for  the  enforceability  of  contracts,"  ibid 
632. 

*  Ibid  630-631.  5  Ibid  631.  6  Ibid  632. 

7  "  La  cause  pour  les  anciens  jurisconsultes  correspond  au  quid  pro  quo  ou  a  la 
consideration  du  droit  anglais ;  ils  ont  pris  pour  point  de  depart  les  idees  romaines  sur 
la  condictio  situ  causa,  sur  les  contrats  innomes.  sur  les  nullites  des  stipulations,  et  de 
la  ont  tire  la  regie ;  pas  d'obligation  sans  cause.  Cil  n'a  mie  bele  reson  de  dtmander, 
dit  P.  de  Fontaines,  qui  demande  por  ce  que  on  li  convenanca,  sanz  autre  reson  metre 
avant.  On  accepta  plus  facilement  ce  principe  qu'il  cadrait  dans  beaucoup  de  cas  avec 
la  theorie  phis  ancienne  de  la  necessite  de  {'execution  au  moins  partielle  du  contract 
pour  qu'il  en  resultat  une  obligation,"  Brissaud,  Droit  Francais  ii  1419-1420. 

8  Pollock,  Contracts  (5th  ed.)  App.  692  ;  cp.  Jazawickreme  v.  Amarasuriya  '1918] 
A.C.  at  p.  875,  where  the  Judicial  Committee  say,  "  It  may  well  be  that  according  to 
English  law,  as  a  general  rule,  an  existing  moral  obligation  not  enforceable  at  law 
does  not  furnish  good  consideration  for  a  subsequent  express  promise :  but  the  Roman 
Dutch  law,  by  which,  in  their  Lordships  view,  this  case  must  be  governed,  is  wholly 
different.  According  to  the  latter  law  it  would  appear  that  a  promise  deliberately 
made  to  discharge  a  moral  duty,  or  to  do  an  act  of  generosity  or  benevolence,  can  be 
enforced  at  law,  the  justa  causa  debendi,  sufficient  according  to  the  latter  system  of 
law,  to  sustain  a  promise,  being  something  far  wider  than  that  which  the  English  law 
treats  as  good  consideration  for  a  promise." 


44      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

able  difficulty  should  have  been  experienced  in  making  a  satisfac- 
tory definition  of  the  term.1  Nor  is  much  light  got  from  the  in- 
terpretation placed  upon  the  clause  of  the  Code  Civil  which  enacts 
that,  "  L' obligation  sans  cause,  ou  sur  un  fausse  cause,  ou  sur  unej^ 
cause  illicite,  ne  peut  avoir  aucun  effet."2  A  contract  is  said  to- 
be  without  a  "cause  "  if  the  parties  did  not  intend  by  their  agree- 
ment to  affect  their  legal  relations,  or  if  the  subject  matter  of  the 
contract  had  perished  before  the  contract  was  made.  It  is  said  to 
have  a  false  "  cause "  if  the  parties  contracted  under  a  mistake 
as  to  the  existence  of  certain  facts,  belief  in  which  induced  the 
making  of  the  contract — e.g.  a  promise  by  A  to  B  to  pay  B  a 
sum  of  money  under  the  false  belief  that  he  owed  him  the  money. 
It  is  said  to  have  an  illegal  cause  if  the  object  of  the  contract  is 
illegal.3  All  this  really  amounts  to  is  that  the  parties  must  have 
intended  by  their  contract  to  affect  their  legal  relations,  that  they 
must  have  really  consented,  and  that  the  object  of  their  contract 
must  be  legal.4  Hence  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  many 
French  writers  reject  the  idea  that  causa  is  needed  for  the  validity 
of  a  contract.  "  They  regard  the  requirement  of  causa  .  .  .  as  an 
abstract  and  metaphysical  notion  calling  for  subtle  distinctions, 
and  creating  confusion  instead  of  serving  a  useful  purpose."  5  The 
same  view  seems  to  be  taken  by  distinguished  Roman-Dutch 
lawyers.  Thus  Professor  Lee  calls  the  requirement  of  causa  "a 
juristic  figment,"6  and  says  that  it  means  little  more  than  that 
"  an  agreement  to  be  legally  enforceable  must  be  entered  upon 
with  a  serious  and  deliberate  mind."  Exactly  the  same  reasoning 
applies  to  causa  as  defined  by  the  Spanish  civil  code,  the  Chilean 
code,  and  the  countries  in  America  which  have  adopted  the 
provisions  of  those  codes.7 

Thus  the  process  of  the  alteration  of  the  Roman  causa  has 
proceeded  continuously  and  logically  to  its  inevitable  result — the 
elimination  of  the  necessity  for  a  causa  as  a  condition  of  the 
validity  of  a  contract.  And,  as  in  Germany  the  same  result  had 
been  produced  by  the  belief  that  the  old  Germanic  law  enforced 
as  a  contract  every  lawful  agreement  intended  to  be  legally  bind- 
ing,8 it  follows  that,  in  most  countries  outside  the  sphere  of  the 
common  law,  the  maxim  ex  nudo  pacto  non  oritur  actio  has  ceased 
to  be  true.      "  Any  pact  whatever,"  says  Professor  Lee,  speaking 

1  "  Many  attempts  have  been  made  to  find  a  general  definition  of  causa,  but  none 
of  them  has  met  with  approval.  .  .  .  Great  difficulty  seems  to  be  experienced  by  the 
French  writers  in  distinguishing  the  causa  of  a  contract,  on  the  one  hand  from  its 
object,  and  on  the  other  hand  from  motive  in  general,"  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  632. 

2  Art.  1133.  s  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  633. 

4  See  Lee,  Introduction  to  Roman  Dutch  Law  198. 

5  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  634,  and  note  75. 

8  Introduction  to  Roman  Dutch  Law  198  n.  2. 

7  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  635.  8  Above  43. 


"  CAUSE  "  AND  CONSIDERATION        45 

of  Roman-Dutch  law,  "  is  enforceable,  provided  only  that  it  is  freely ^ 
entered  upon  by  competent  persons  for  an  object  which  is  physic- 
ally possible  and  legally  permissible"  j1  and  the  same  description, 
it  would  seem,  might  be  given  of  either  the  actual  state  of  the  law, 
or  the  state  to  which  it  is  approximating,  in  all  civilized  countries 
which  are  not  governed  by  the  common  law.  The  result  is  a 
striking  illustration  of  the  truth  of  Lord  Denman's  dictum  that, 
the  doctrine  that  moral  obligation  is  a  sufficient  consideration 
"  would  annihilate  the  necessity  for  any  consideration  at  all,  inas- 
much as  the  mere  fact  of  giving  a  promise  creates  a  moral 
obligation  to  perform  it''  2 

The  adoption  by  the  law  of  this  liberal  attitude  ensures  the 
carrying  out  of  the  lawful  intentions  of  contracting  parties  ;  and,  if 
it  is  right  that  the  law  should  enforce  contracts,  there  seems  no 
good  reason  why  it  should  not  at  the  present  day  adopt  this 
attitude.  There  seems  to  be  no  reason  why  it  should  allow  itself 
to  be  fettered,  either  by  obsolete  procedural  difficulties,  or  by 
obsolete  technicalities  which  have  been  inherited  from  other  legal 
systems.  But  undoubtedly  such  a  system  of  contract  law  has  its 
weak  points.  In  the  first  place,  there  is  the  difficulty  of  proving 
the  contract ;  and,  in  the  second  place,  there  is  the  difficulty  of 
proving  whether  or  not  the  parties  really  intended  by  their  agree- 
ment to  affect  their  legal  relations.  Both  these  questions  may 
raise  very  difficult  questions  of  fact.  But  these  difficulties  may  be 
obviated  by  requiring,  as  French  law  requires,  all  contracts  which 
involve  more  than  a  certain  sum  of  money  to  be  in  writing  ;3  and 
by  requiring,  as  is  done  in  many  countries,  that  promises  to  give 
shall  be  authenticated  by  a  judge  or  notary.4 

Continental  systems  of  law,  therefore,  by  gradually  altering, 
and  then  in  effect  dropping,  the  doctrine  of  causa,  have  worked  out 
a  theory  of  contract  very  different  from  the  English  system  based 
on  the  doctrine  of  consideration.  But  it  will  be  clear  that,  if  the 
eighteenth-century  theories  of  moral  obligation,  and  still  more 
if  the  theory  put  forward  by  Lord  Mansfield  in  Pillans  v.  Van 
Mierop,  had  prevailed,  the  English  theory  of  contract  would  now 
be  approaching  very  closely  to  the  continental  system.  It  is  worthy 
of  note  that,  in  the  case  of  Pillans  v.  Van  Mierop,  Wilmot,  J.,  to 
a  large  extent,  based  his  judgment  on  an  identification  of  the 
civilian  causa  with  the  English  consideration.5  As  the  civilians 
held  that  there  could  be  no  nudum  pactum  when  the  agreement 

1  Op.  cit.  197.  *  Eastwood  v.  Kenyon  (1840)  11  Ad.  and  E.  at  p.  450. 

3  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  642,  citing  Art.  1341  of  the  Civil  Code ;  for  a  similar 
rule  in  Scotland  see  Bell,  Principles  §§  63,  67,  cited  [191S]  A.C.  at  p.  875  n.  2. 

*  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  643,  citing  the  codes  of  France,  Germany,  and  Italy. 
5  (T765)  3  Burr,  at  pp.  1670,  1671. 


46       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

was  put  into  writing,  because  the  writing  made  a  causa,  so  in 
England  writing  should  supply  the  place  of  consideration.  But  we 
have  seen  that  this  theory  was  never  accepted  ;  and  that,  in  the 
second  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century,  the  theory  that  moral 
obligation  was  a  valid  consideration  was  rejected.  Both  these  lines 
of  development,  therefore,  were  closed. 

Instead,  a  return  was  made  to  those  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
century  cases,  in  which  the  doctrine  of  consideration  was  being 
developed  from  the  procedural  necessities  of  the  action  of  assumpsit. 
Thus  the  English  theory  of  contract  is  still  bound  up  with  the 
conditions  imposed  upon  it  by  the  form  of  action  through  which 
contracts,  other  than  specialty  contracts,  became  enforceable. 

No  doubt  the  resulting  theory  of  contract  has  its  strong  points. 
"Roughly  stated  it  seems  plain  and  sensible,  the  court  will  hold 
people  to  their  bargains,  but  will  not  enforce  gratuitous  promises 
unless  they  are  made  in  solemn  form." 1  It  is  in  fact  strong  where 
the  rival  theory  is  weak.  But  it  may  be  questioned  whether,  in 
its  present  form,  its  weaknesses  do  not  outweigh  its  advantages. 
Some  of  its  weaknesses  have  been  very  clearly  pointed  out 
by  Mark  by.2  A  gratuitous  promise  is  not  actionable  unless  it  is 
made  in  writing  under  seal ;  but  the  court  will  not  enquire  into 
'the  adequacy  of  the  consideration,  and  a  mere  nominal  considera- 
tion will  suffice.  Why  should  not  the  performance  by  A  of  his 
duty  under  his  contract  with  B,  be  a  consideration  for  a  promise 
by  C  to  A  ?  Why  should  not  a  promise  to  keep  an  offer  open  for 
a  week,  or  a  promise  to  release  a  debt  in  consideration  of  part  pay- 
ment, be  valid  ?  Why,  in  fact,  should  not  any  promise  be  binding 
if  the  party  promising  intended  to  put  himself  under  a  legal 
liability  ?  The  requirement  of  consideration  in  its  present  shape 
prevents  the  enforcement  of  many  contracts,  which  ought  to  be 
enforced,  if  the  law  really  wishes  to  give  effect  to  the  lawful  inten- 
tions of  the  parties  to  them  ;  and  it  would  prevent  the  enforcement 
of  many  others,  if  the  judges  had  not  used  their  ingenuity  to  invent 
considerations.  But  the  invention  of  considerations,  by  reasoning 
which  is  both  devious  and  technical,  adds  to  the  difficulties  of  the 
doctrine.3  Markby  s  strictures  have  recently  gained  an  increasing 
measure  of  support.  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  said  that  the  application 
of  the  doctrine  "  to  various  unusual  but  not  unknown  cases  has 
been  made  subtle  and  obscure  by  excessive  dialectic  refinement."  4 

1  Pollock,  Genius  of  the  Common  Law,  91. 

2  Elements  of  Law  (3rd  ed.)  310-317. 

3  "  In  some  cases  where  it  was  clear  that  contractual  liability  ought  to  be  re- 
cognised, they  have  found  great  difficulty  in  recognising  it,  because  they  could  not  find 
any  '  consideration,'  although  there  was  ample  other  indication  of  intention.  They 
have  in  most  cases  managed  to  get  over  the  difficulty,  but  by  reasoning  which  is  the 
reverse  of  satisfactory,"  Markby,  op.  cit.  311, 

4  Genius  of  the  Common  Law^gi. 


"  CAUSE  "  AND  CONSIDERATION        47 

In  a  recent  case  Lord  Dunedin  said,1  "  I  confess  that  this  case  is 
to  my  mind  apt  to  nip  any  budding  affection  which  one  might 
have  had  for  the  doctrine  of  consideration.  For  the  effect  of  that 
doctrine  in  the  present  case  is  to  make  it  possible  for  a  person  to 
snap  his  fingers  at  a  bargain  deliberately  made,  a  bargain  not  in 
itself  unfair,  and  which  the  person  seeking  to  enforce  it  has  a  legiti- 
mate interest  to  enforce."  Professor  Lorenzen,  in  an  able  article 
in  the  Yale  Law  Journal,  to  which  I  am  much  indebted,  takes  sub- 
stantially the  same  view.2 

In  fact,  the  doctrine  of  consideration  in  its  present  form  is 
something  of  an  anachronism.  The  substantive  law  has  long  ago 
broken  away  from  the  leading  strings  of  the  forms  of  action,  and 
the  law  of  actions  has  become  merely  adjective  law.  But  our 
theory  of  contract  is  still  governed  by  a  doctrine  which  is  histori- 
cally developed,  with  great  logical  precision,  from  the  procedural 
requirements  of  the  form  of  action  by  which  simple  contracts  were 
enforced.  These  procedural  requirements  were  not  mere  matters 
of  form.  They  were  the  conditions  precedent  for  applying  the 
remedy  which  was  the  best,  and  in  many  cases  the  only  remedy, 
which  the  common  law  possessed  for  the  enforcement  of  contracts. 
Thus  it  happens  that  it  has  not  been  possible  to  treat  the  doctrine 
of  consideration  as  mere  form.  It  has  been  necessary  to  treat  it  as 
the  essential  condition  for  the  validity  of  all  simple  contracts. 

There  is,  it  seems  to  me,  good  sense  in  Lord  Mansfield's  view 
that  consideration  should  be  treated,  not  as  the  sole  test  of  the 
validity  of  a  simple  contract,  but  simply  as  a  piece  of  evidence 
which  proves  its  conclusion.  This  is  in  effect  the  view  which  he 
tried  to  enforce  in  Pillans  v.  Van  Mierop  ;3  and  though,  like 
some  of  his  other  rulings,4  it  was  demonstrably  not  English  law,  it 
embodied  a  true  idea  of  the  tendency  of  legal  development  The 
consequence  of  adopting  this  view  would  be  that  any  lawful  agree- 
ment into  which  the  parties  to  it  entered  with  the  intention  of 
affecting   their   legal  relations,5  would,  if  it  could  be  proved  by 

1  Dunlop  Pneumatic  Tyre  Co.  v.  Selfridge  and  Co.  [1915]  A.C.  at  p.  855 ;  it  might 
however  be  contended  that  the  refusal  to  uphold  the  validity  of  the  contract  in  this  case 
was  on  the  whole  in  accordance  with  public  policy,  as  a  contrary  decision  would  have 
facilitated  the  operations  of  a  design  to  keep  up  prices  as  against  the  public  ;  but  this 
does  not  affect  the  main  argument. 

*  "  Subject  to  certain  qualifications  relating  to  form,  it  should  suffice  for  the  forma- 
tion of  contracts  that  there  exist  (1)  capacity  ;  (2)  an  intention  to  contract ;  and  (3)  a 
possible  and  lawful  object,"  Yale  Law  Journal  xxviii  646. 

s  Above  29-30.  *  Vol.  vii  45. 

5  This  must  of  course  be  a  condition  precedent  in  any  body  of  contract  law ;  for  a  good 
and  recent  instance  where  an  agreement  was  held  to  be  unenforceable  on  the  ground  that 
no  such  intention  existed,  see  Balfour  v.  Balfour  [1919]  2  K.B.  571 ;  and  cp.  Rose  and 
Frank  Co.  v.  Crompton  and  Bros.  [1923]  2  K.B.  261,  [1925]  A.C.  at  p.  454,  where  it 
was  held  that  the  agreement  of  the  parties  was  not  enforceable  because  they  had  ex- 
pressly negatived  an  intention  to  create  any  legal  obligations ;  note  also  that  exactly 
the  same  principle  has  been  applied  by  Tomlin,  J.,  to  the  creation  of  a  trust,  In  re 


48       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

adequate  evidence,  be  enforceable.  The  intention  of  the  parties 
to  enter  into  a  lawful  agreement  affecting  their  legal  relations 
would  be  the  main  thing.  If  that  was  proved  the  agreement 
would  be  enforceable. 

We  have  seen  that  in  Continental  states  difficulties  of  proof 
have  made  it  impossible  to  adopt  an  attitude  quite  so  liberal  as 
this  ; l  and  to  introduce  any  such  rule  into  the  law  of  this  country 
would  make  a  total  break  with  all  existing  rules  of  English  law. 
But  it  is  at  least  arguable  that  the  time  has  come  to  make  some 
sort  of  a  change.  A  legal  history  is  not  perhaps  the  place  to 
make  suggestions  as  to  the  law  of  the  future.  It  is  concerned  with 
the  past.  But,  if  history  is  to  be  something  more  than  mere 
antiquarianism,  it  should  be  able  to  originate  suggestions  as  to  the 
best  way  in  which  reforms  in  the  law  might  be  carried  out,  so  as 
to  make  it  conform  with  present  needs.  The  doctrine  of  consider- 
ation has,  as  we  have  seen,  its  strong  points.  Its  weakness  is  that, 
it  is  inadequate  as  the  sole  test  of  the  validity  of  simple  contracts. 
The  true  remedy,  therefore,  is  not  to  scrap  it,  but  to  reduce  it  to 
a  subordinate  place  in  the  English  theory  of  contract.  This,  it 
seems  to  me,  could  be  done,  and  at  the  same  time  a  great  simpli- 
fication could  be  made  in  the  English  law  of  contract,  if  a  short 
Act  were  passed  which,  (i)  abolished  the  differences  between 
simple  and  specialty  contracts  ; 2  (2)  repealed  §  4  of  the  statute 
of  Frauds  and  §  4  of  the  Sale  of  Goods  Act;3  and  (3)  provided 
that  all  lawful  agreements  should  be  valid  contracts,  if  the  parties 
intended  by  their  agreement  to  affect  their  legal  relations,  and 
either  consideration  was  present,  or  the  agreement  was  put  into 
writing  and  signed  by  all  the  parties  thereto.  By  making  these 
changes  we  should  get  a  body  of  law  which  would  be  easy  to 
apply,  and  would  allow  a  greatly  increased  freedom  of  contract. 
The  need  for  proof  that  the  parties  to  the  contract  intended  to 
affect  their  legal  relations  would  be  satisfied ;  proof  of  the  exis- 
tence of  the  contract  would  be  facilitated ;  and,  at  the  same  time, 
full  effect  could  be  given  to  the  intention  of  persons  who  wish  to 
enter  into  contractual  relations. 

But  it  is  time  to  return  from  these  anticipations  of  the  future 
to  the  law  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries. 


Falkiner  [1924]  1  Ch.  88  ;  in  fact  in  equity  this  principle  has  long  been  recognized,  see 
Lord  Walpole  v.  Lord  Oxford  [1797]  3  Ves.  at  p.  419;  Maunsell  v.  Hedges  (1854) 
4  H.L.C.  1039 ;  Jorden  v.  Money  (1854)  5  H.L.C.  185. 

1  Above  45. 

2  Something  like  this  has  already  been  affected  in  the  law  as  to  the  administration 
of  assets  by  32,  33  Victoria  c  46  ;  Re  Samson  [1906]  2  Ch.  584. 

3  It  might  be  necessary  to  reconsider  other  statutes  which  impose  restrictions  of 
form  ;  the  rule  that  the  contracts  of  corporations  must  be  under  seal  would  not  neces- 
sarily be  affected,  but  they  would  cease  to  be  specialty  contracts, 


INVALIDITY  49 

§    2.    THE   INVALIDITY,    ENFORCEMENT,    AND   DISCHARGE  OF 
CONTRACTS 

The  growth  of  rules  upon  the  first  of  these  topics  was  due, 
partly  to  the  working  out  of  the  consequences  of  the  fact  that  the 
essence  of  contract  is  agreement,  and  partly  to  the  necessity  of 
bringing  the  rules  of  contract  law  into  line  with  the  law  of  status 
and  the  law  of  crime  and  tort  Thus  we  get  the  growth  of  rules 
as  to  the  effect  of  mistake,  as  to  the  contractual  capacity  of  married 
women  and  infants,  and  as  to  the  effect  of  illegality  of  object ;  and 
the  growth  of  these  and  other  rules  gradually  enables  the  law  to 
draw  distinctions  between  different  grades  of  invalidity — between 
contracts  which  are  void,  contracts  which  are  voidable,  and  con- 
tracts which  are  unenforceable.  But,  just  as  the  different  rules 
which  make  up  the  doctrine  of  consideration  were  gradually 
developed  from  the  procedural  rules  which  regulated  the  compet- 
ence of  the  action  of  assumpsit,  so  some  of  the  rules  as  to  the 
invalidity  of  contracts,  the  greater  part  of  the  rules  which  regulated 
the  conditions  under  which  the  parties  could  enforce  their  contracts, 
and  the  forms  and  modes  of  discharge,  were  gradually  built  up 
from  the  same  procedural  basis.  It  is  true  that  some  of  these 
rules  owed  something  to  the  mediaeval  rules  as  to  covenants  and 
conditions  contained  in  deeds,  which,  for  the  most  part,  related 
to  the  land  law ;  and  that  other  doctrines,  eg.  the  rules  as  to 
payment  and  tender,  which  first  made  their  appearance  in  con- 
nection with  the  land  law,1  were  adapted  to  the  law  of  contract. 
But  most  of  the  substantive  rules  of  our  modern  law  were  built 
up  from  decisions  as  to  the  rights  of  the  parties  in  personal  actions, 
and  more  especially  in  actions  of  assumpsit,  brought  to  enforce 
contracts;  and  it  is  only  when  these  decisions  have  begun  to 
accumulate,  that  the  substantive  rules  begin  to  take  their  modern 
shape. 

During  this  period  these  rules  are  for  the  most  part  only 
beginning  to  be  developed.  In  many  cases  their  later  develop- 
ment is  the  work  of  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries,  and 
will  be  related  in  the  succeeding  Book  of  this  History.  In  these 
cases,  therefore,  it  will  only  be  possible  at  this  point  to  indicate 
briefly  the  origins  of  some  of  these  rules,  under  the  three  heads 
which  I  have  indicated. 

Invalidity 

That  the  absence  of  consideration  made  a  contract  invalid 
followed,  as  we  have  seen,  from  the  procedural  requirements  of 
assumpsit.     Further  causes  of  invalidity  flowed  from  the  nature 

1  Vol.  ii  5go  and  n.  4. 
VOL.  VIIL— 4 


50      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

of  an  agreement,  the  incapacity  of  the  parties,  illegality  of  object, 
impossibility,  the  alteration  of  a  contract  under  seal,  and  the  effect 
of  statutory  provisions.  With  these  causes  of  invalidity  I  shall  deal 
in  the  first  place.  Secondly,  I  shall  deal  with  one  of  the  results  of 
these  causes  of  invalidity — the  elucidation  of  the  distinction  between 
void,  voidable,  and  unenforceable  contracts.  Thirdly,  I  shall  say 
something  of  the  effects  of  fraud  and  misrepresentation,  and  explain 
why  at  this  period  these  topics  have  not  assumed  the  place  which 
they  will  occupy  in  our  modern  law  of  contract. 

(i)   Causes  of  invalidity. 

Causes  arising  from  the  nature  of  an  agreement. 

We  have  seen  that  the  contract  under  seal  was  the  only  purely 
consensual  contract  known  to  the  mediaeval  common  law.1  It  is 
not  surprising,  therefore,  to  find  that  the  early  authorities  on  con- 
tracts invalid  by  reason  of  circumstances  vitiating  consent  are  all 
concerned  with  these  contracts  under  seal.  As  early  as  Edward  I.'s 
reign  Fleta  stated  that  a  deed  executed  under  a  mistake  as  to  its 
contents  and  without  negligence  was  not  binding.2  But  we  have 
seen  that  the  mediaeval  common  law  had  not  acquired  a  doctrine 
of  negligence ; 3  and  so,  in  the  Year  Books,  Fleta's  rule  was  stated 
in  the  following  form :  if  an  unlearned  man,  to  whom  the  provi- 
sions of  a  deed  had  been  wrongly  read,  executed  it  under  a 
mistake  as  to  its  contents,  he  could  say  that  it  was  not  his  deed.4 
The  principle  of  these  cases  was  summed  up  by  Coke  in  Thorough- 
good's  Case5  (1584),  where  it  was  held  that  if  an  illiterate  man 
was  induced,  either  by  a  party  to  the  deed  or  by  a  stranger,  to 
deliver  as  his  deed  a  document  which  contained  provisions  quite 
different  from  those  which  he  intended,  the  deed  was  void.  Clearly 
this  decision  depends  at  bottom  on  the  principle  that  the  party  so 
deceived  has  never  consented.  The  fact  that  the  person  deceived 
was  illiterate  is  really  immaterial,  as  was  seen  by  some  of  the 
judges0  before  Thoroughgood's  Case  was  decided,  provided,  as 
Fleta  in  the  thirteenth  century,7  and  as  the  later  cases  point  out,8 

1  Vol.  iii  420. 

2  "  Si  autem  vocatus  dicat  quod  carta  sibi  nocere  non  debeat  .  .  .  quia  per  dolum 
advenit  ut  si  cartam  de  feoffamento  sigillatam  (qu.  sigillavit  or  sigillaverit)  cum  scrip- 
turn  de  termino  annorum  sigillare  crediderit,  vel  ut  si  carta  fieri  debuit  ad  vitam,  illam 
fecit  fieri  in  feodo  et  hujusmodi,  dum  tamen  nihil  sit  quod  imperitiae  vel  negligentiae 
sua;  possit  imputari,"  Heta,  6.  33.  2,  cited  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  502  n.  (/). 

3  Vol.  iii  375.  *  Y.BB.  30  Ed.  III.  31b  ;  9  Hy.  VI.  Hil.  pi.  8  per  Paston,  J. 

5  2  Co.  Rep.  ga ;  cp.  Pigot's  Case  (1615)  n  Co.  Rep.  at  ff.  27b,  28a. 

6  "  Nota  que  fuit  dit  per  Frowike  et  Kingsmill  que  lou  jeo  desire  un  home  que  il 
voit  moy  enfeffer  dun  acre  del  terre  en  Dale,  et  il  moy  command  de  faire  un  fait  dun 
acre  del  terre  ove  letter  d'attorney,  et  jeo  face  le  fait  de  deux  acres,  et  lie  et  declare  le 
fait  a  luy  forsque  dun  acre,  et  il  enseale  le  fait,  cest  fait  est  merement  voide  lequel  le 
feoffor  soit  letter  au  nient  letter,"  Anon.  (1506)  Keil.  70  pi.  6. 

7  Above  n.  2. 

8  Foster  v.  Mackinnon  (1869)  L.R.  4  C.P.  at  p.  712. 


INVALIDITY  51 

there  has  been  no  negligence.  It  was  inevitable  that,  as  the  idea 
that  the  essence  of  contract  is  consent  became  more  distinctly 
realized,  the  principle  should  be  applied  to  all  kinds  of  contracts. 
In  1869  it  was  applied  to  a  case  where  a  man  was  induced  to  in- 
dorse a  bill  of  exchange  by  the  fraudulent  representation  of  the 
acceptor  that  he  was  signing  a  guarantee  ; x  and  other  modern  cases 
afford  illustrations  of  different  varieties  of  this  fundamental  error 
or  common  mistake,  which,  because  it  excludes  consent,  prevents 
the  conclusion  of  any  contract.2 

Similarly,  there  was  authority  in  the  Year  Books  that  an  agree- 
ment induced  by  threats  or  violence  could  be  avoided,3  because  in 
such  a  case  consent  was  not  freely  given.4  "  If  a  stranger  menace 
A  to  make  a  deed  to  B,  A  shall  avoid  the  deed  which  he  made  by 
such  threats  as  well  as  if  B  himself  had  threatened  him."5  This 
was  a  slight  advance  on  some  of  the  earlier  authorities,  which  had 
refused  to  pay  any  attention  to  duress  by  a  stranger ; 6  but  the 
common  law  still  continued  to  take  so  narrow  a  view  of  what 
constituted  duress "  that  there  was  abundant  need  for  the  creation 
and  elaboration  by  equity  of  a  doctrine  of  undue  influence  as  a 
supplementary  cause  of  invalidity.  It  was,  however,  very  early 
recognized  that  the  effect  of  duress  was  different  from  the  effect  of 
a  common  mistake.  Inasmuch  as  consent  had  been  given,  though 
not  freely  given,  the  effect  was  to  render  the  deed  not  void  but 
voidable.8 

Causes  arising  from  the  incapacity  of  the  parties. 

That  a  married  woman's  contract  was,  with  very  few  exceptions, 
absolutely  void,  was  a  principle  which  had  been  clearly  ascertained 
in  the  Middle  Ages.9  On  the  other  hand,  it  was  reasonably  clear 
that  an  infant's  contract,  other  than  a  contract  for  necessaries,  was 
voidable  at  his  option  ; 10  and  it  was  settled  early  in  the  seventeenth 

1  Foster  v.  Mackinnon  L.R.  4  C.P.  704. 

2  See  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  149-159. 

3  Y.BB.  1  Hy.  VII.  Pasch.  pi.  2  (p.  15)  per  Keble  org.;  14  Hy.  VIII.  Pasch.  pi. 
7  (p.  28)  per  Pollard,  J. 

4  Y.B.  21  Ed.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  4  (p.  13),  and  Pasch.  pi.  22  per  Collow  org. 

5  Thoroughgood's  Case  (1584)  2  Co.  rtep.  at  f.  gb. 

6  "  Le  defendant  en  dette  plede  que  il  fist  l'obligacion  al  plaintif  per  duresse  den- 
prisonment  dun  estrange,  et  demanda  judgement  si  accion.  Et  lopinion  de  Rede  et 
auters  que  ceo  nest  plea  sans  faire  obligee  partie  a  cest  duresse,"  Anon.  (1509)  Keil. 
x54  pl-  3 '■>  though  it  was  admitted  that,  "  dures  per  estranger  per  procurement  del 
partie  que  avera  benefit  est  bon  cause  d'avoider,"  Rolle  Ab.  Dures  C.  1,  citing  Y.B. 
43  Ed.  III.  Hil.  pi.  15. 

7  See  Huscombe  v.  Standing  (1608)  Cro.  Jac.  187  where  it  was  held  that  if  a  bond 
be  obtained  from  A  and  B,  B  being  A's  surety,  by  duress  against  A,  B  could  not  plead 
the  duress  in  discharge  of  the  bond. 

8  Y.BB.  cited  n.  3;  Whelpdale's  Case  (1605)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  119a;  Dive  v. 
Manningham  (1551)  Plowden  at  p.  66  cited  below  65-66. 

9  Vol.  iii  528. 

10  Y.B.  i  Hy.  VII.  Pasch.  pi.  2  (p.  15)  where  the  infant's  and  the  married  woman's 
contracts  are  contrasted  from  this  point  of  view  ;  Whelpdale's  Case  (1605)  5  Co.  Rep. 
at  f.  119a;  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  59-60,  74;  vol.  iii  518-519. 


52       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

century  that,  if  an  infant  took  a  lease  of  property,  he  was  liable  for 
the  rent,  if  he  did  not  repudiate  it  during  his  infancy.1  Moreover, 
the  court  was  careful  to  safeguard  the  infant's  liability  for  neces- 
saries. A  bond  for  the  payment  of  money  lent,  though  it  was  for 
the  purchase  of  necessaries;2  and  a  contract  to  buy  goods  "to 
maintain  his  trade  though  he  gain  thereby  his  living"  did  not  bind 
him.3  Whether  or  not  the  infant's  liability  was  truly  contractual, 
so  that  he  was  liable  to  pay  the  contract  price,  or  whether  it  was 
rather  quasi-contractual,  so  that  he  was  only  liable  to  pay  a  reason- 
able price,  was  not  as  yet  clearly  ascertained.  We  have  seen  that 
in  the  Middle  Ages  there  is  some  authority  for  the  proposition  that, 
the  action  of  debt  lay  against  him,  and  if  this  action  lay  it  could 
be  brought  only  for  the  contract  price.4  It  is  clear,  too,  that  for 
the  rent  reserved  on  a  lease  made  during  infancy  he  could  be  sued 
by  action  of  debt,5  for  otherwise  he  could  not  have  been  sued  at 
all.6  But  in  many  cases  where  he  was  sued  for  necessaries  the 
form  of  the  action  was  assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit ; 7  and  in 
this  action  the  plaintiff  could  obviously  recover  only  a  reasonable 
price.  Thus  the  form  of  the  action  usually  employed  gave  rise  to 
the  modern  idea,  to  which  effect  is  given  by  the  Sale  of  Goods 
Act,8  that  his  liability  for  necessaries  is  rather  quasi-contractual 
than  contractual.9 

The  treatment  by  the  law  of  the  contracts  of  drunken  persons 
or  lunatics  was  for  some  time  uncertain.10  Coke,  speaking  of  dis- 
positions of  their  property  made  by  them,  laid  it  down  that  the 
lunatic  and  idiot,  and  a  fortiori  the  drunkard  whose  disability  was 
his  own  fault,  could  not  be  allowed  to  avoid  them ; u  and  presum- 
ably he  would  have  applied  the  same  principles  to  their  contracts.12 

1  Ketsey's  Case  (1614)  Cro.  Jac.  320. 

2  "  An  infant  may  bind  himself  to  pay  for  his  necessary  meat,  drink,  apparel, 
necessary  physick,  and  such  other  necessaries,  and  likewise  for  his  good  teaching  or 
instruction,  whereby  he  may  profit  himself  afterwards ;  but  if  he  bind  himself  in  an 
obligation  or  other  writing,  with  a  penalty  for  the  payment  of  any  of  these,  that  obli- 
gation shall  not  bind  him,"  Co.  Litt.  172a. 

3  Whittingham  v.  Hill  (1619)  Cro.  Jac.  494. 

4  Vol.  iii  519  n.  5;  this  was  assumed  to  be  good  law  in  Makarell  v.  Bachelor 
(1598)  Cro.  Eliza.  583. 

6  Ketsey's  Case  (1614)  Cro.  Jac.  320.  6  Vol.  vii  263,  272. 

7  See  e.g.  Ive  v.  Chester  (1620)  Cro.  Jac.  560;  Rainsford  v.  Fenwick  (1670) 
Carter  215. 

8  56,  57  Victoria  c.  71  §  2. 

9  Nash  v.  Inman  [1908]  2  K.B,  at  pp.  8-g  per  Fletcher-Moulton,  L.J. 

10  On  this  topic  see  generally  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  96-101. 

11  "  As  for  a  drunkard,  who  is  voluntarius  daemon,  he  hath  (as  hath  been  said)  no 
privilege  thereby.  .  .  .  And  if  an  idiot  make  a  feoffment  in  fee,  he  shall  in  pleading 
never  avoid  it  by  saying  that  he  was  an  idiot  at  the  time  of  his  feoffment,"  Co.  Litt. 
247a. 

12  "  Every  deed  feoffment  or  grant,  which  any  man  non  compos  mentis  makes,  is 
avoidable,  and  yet  shall  not  be  avoided  by  himself,  because  it  is  a  maxim  in  law,  that 
no  man  of  full  age  shall  be  in  any  plea  to  be  pleaded  by  him,  received  by  the  law  to 
stultify  himself,  and  disable  his  own  person,"  Beverley's  Case  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep.  at 
f.  123a. 


INVALIDITY  53 

But  it  is  doubtful  if  this  was  ever  really  accepted  as  law.  It  was 
certainly  not  the  law  of  Bracton's  day,  who  on  this  point  followed 
Roman  law;1  and  Fitzherbert  expressly  dissents  from  it,  and 
maintains  that  the  dealings  by  a  lunatic  with  his  property  were, 
like  the  dealings  of  an  infant,  voidable.2  In  the  eighteenth  cen- 
tury it  was  thought  that,  if  the  lunacy  or  drunkenness  was  so 
complete  that  the  lunatic  or  drunkard  was  incapable  of  consent, 
the  contract  was  void.3  But  there  are  many  cases  in  which  a  man 
is  a  lunatic  or  drunk,  but  not  completely  incapacitated  ;  and  it  may 
well  be  that  his  state  is  not  immediately  obvious  to  the  other  con- 
tracting party.  It  would  be  hard  to  rule  that  in  such  cases  the 
contract  was  wholly  void ;  and  so  in  1 848  the  principle  which 
had  been  for  some  time  acted  on  by  the  court  of  Chancery 4  was 
adopted ;  and  it  was  laid  down  that  a  contract  entered  into  by  a 
lunatic  or  drunken  person  makes  the  contract  voidable  at  his 
option,  provided  that  his  state  was  known  to  the  other  contract- 
ing party.5 

Illegality  of  object. 

That  an  agreement  to  do  something  contrary  to  law  is  void 
has  necessarily  been  recognized  from  the  earliest  times.  M  If,"  it 
was  said  in  Dive  v.  Manningham?  "  the  obligation  was  to  save 
one  harmless  if  he  killed  such  an  one  or  did  such  a  trespass,  the 
obligation  should  be  void.  So  shall  it  be  here,  for  the  obligation 
is  to  save  the  sheriff  harmless  for  doing  a  tort  and  a  thing  contrary 
to  law,  in  which  case  the  obligation  is  void  by  the  course  of  the 
common  law ".  There  are  many  cases  of  this  period  which  lay 
down  the  principle  that,  if  the  whole  consideration  for  a  contract 
is  illegal,  the  contract  is  void ; "  and  this  is  still  the  law,  for  the 
illegality  of  the  consideration  vitiates  the  whole.8  In  certain  of 
these  cases,  however,  we  can  see  the  origin  of  distinctions  which, 
to  some  extent,  limit  the  generality  of  this  principle.  Two  of 
these  distinctions  are  well  established  in  our  modern  law,  and  the 
third  is  obsolete. 

(i)  If  some  of  the  stipulations  in  a  contract  are  legal  and  some 
are  illegal,  and  it  is  possible  to  sever  the  legal  from  the  illegal,  the 
court  will  make  this  severance,  and  enforce  those  which  are  legal. 

1 "  Furiosus  autem  stipulari  non  potest,  nee  aliquod  negotium  agere,  quia  non  in- 
telligit  quid  agit,"  f.  iooa. 

*  F.N.B.  202  D. 

3  Yates  v.  Boen  (1739)  2  Str.  1104;  Pitt  v.  Smith  (1811)  3  Camp.  33;  Pollock, 
Contracts  9S-100. 

4  Ibid  98  n.  (g). 

5  Molton  v.  Camroux  (1S48)  2  Ex.  487,  4  Ex.  17. 

*  (1551)  Plowden  at  p.  64. 

7  Bridge  v.  Cage  (1606)  Cro.  Jac  103  ;  Mackeller  v.  Todderick  (1634)  Cro.  Car. 
337 1  Kosindale's  Case  cited  in  Hussey  v.  Jacob  (1697)  x  Ed.  Raym.  at  p.  89. 

8  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  443-444. 


54       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

"  It  is  unanimously  agreed  in  14  H.  8  25,  26  that  if  some  of  the 
covenants  of  an  indenture,  or  of  the  conditions  endorsed  upon  a 
bond,  are  against  law,  and  some  good  and  lawful  ;  that  in  this 
case  the  covenants  or  conditions  which  are  against  law  are  void  ab 
initio,  and  the  others  stand  good."1  (ii)  It  was  settled  in  1623 
that  if  one  man  makes  a  promise  to  another,  in  consideration  of 
the  performance  of  a  service  by  that  other,  which  is  not  manifestly 
unlawful,  and  is  not  known  to  the  person  who  performs  it  to  be 
unlawful,  the  fact  that  it  is  unlawful  will  be  no  answer  to  an  action 
on  the  promise  to  pay  for  it.2  "  If  I  request  one  man  to  enter  into 
another  man's  ground,  and  in  my  name  drive  out  the  beasts  and 
impound  them,  and  promise  to  save  him  harmless,  this  is  a  good 
assumpsit,  and  yet  the  act  is  tortious ;  but  .  .  .  where  the  act 
appears  in  itself  to  be  unlawful,  then  it  is  otherwise,  as  if  I  request 
you  to  beat  another,  and  promise  to  save  you  harmless,  this  as- 
sumpsit is  not  good."3  (iii)  It  was  at  one  time  thought  that  the 
operation  of  a  statute  in  making  a  contract  void  was  wider  than 
the  operation  of  the  common  law.  In  1669  Twisden,  J.,  said4 
that  he  had  heard  Hobart  say  that  "  the  statute  is  like  a  tyrant ; 
where  he  comes  he  makes  all  void  ;  but  the  common  law  is  like 
a  nursing  father,  and  makes  void  only  that  part  where  the  fault  is 
and  preserves  the  rest " ;  and  there  was  some  authority  in  favour 
of  this  view.5  But  it  was  repudiated  by  Wilmot,  C.J.,  in  Collins 
v.  Blantern  ; 6  and  it  is  long  ago  settled  that  no  such  principle  is 
law.  The  extent  of  the  operation  of  a  statute  depends  entirely 
upon  its  wording.7 

Historically,  by  far  the  most  interesting  branch  of  this  cause 
of  the  invalidity  of  contracts  is  that  which  is  compendiously 
grouped  under  the  head  of  "  public  policy."  At  the  present  day  a 
number  of  contracts  are  held  to  be  void  for  illegality  of  object, 
because  they  aim  at  effecting  certain  results  which  it  is  the  policy 
of  the  law  to  prevent. 8 

It  has  very  often  been  said,  and  rightly  said,  that  "public 
policy"  "  is  a  vague  and  unsatisfactory  term  and  calculated  to  lead 
to  uncertainty  and  error  when  applied  to  the  decision  of  legal 
rights " ; 9  for   in   its   ordinary  sense  it  means  little   more  than 

1  Pigot's  Case  (1615)  n  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  27b;  cp.  Pickering  v.  Ilfracombe  Kailway 
Co.  (1868)  L.R.  3  C.P.  at  p.  250.  2  Battersey's  Case  (1623)  Winch.  48. 

3  At  p.  49.  4Maleverer  v.  Redshaw  i  Mod.  35. 

5  "  A  statute  is  a  strict  law ;  but  the  common  law  doth  divide  according  to  common 
reason,  and  having  made  that  void  that  is  against  law,  lets  the  rest  stand,"  Norton  v. 
Simmes  (1615)  Hob.  at  p.  14. 

6  "  I  think  there  is  no  difference  between  things  made  void  by  Act  of  Parliament, 
and  things  void  by  the  common  law,"  (1767)  2  Wils.  at  p.  351. 

7  Pickering  v.  Ilfracombe  Railway  Co.  (1868)  L.R.  3  C.P.  at  p.  250. 

8  See  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  221-230. 

"Egerton  v.  Brownlow  (1853)  4  H.L.C.  at  p.  123  per  Parke,  B. ;  cp.  the  similar 
but  less  cautious  statement  of  Lord  Halsbury  in  Janson  v.  Driefontein  Mines  Ltd. 
[1902]  A.C.  at  p.  491. 


INVALIDITY  55 

political  expediency,  which  is  a  matter  for  the  consideration  of  the 
statesman  and  not  of  the  judge.  But  Parke,  B.,  who  used  these 
words,  admitted  that  some  decisions  have  been  founded  "  upon  the 
prevailing  and  just  opinions  of  the  public  good ;  for  instance  the 
illegality  of  covenants  in  restraint  of  marriage  or  trade  "  ; 1  and  he 
pointed  out  that  "  public  policy,"  if  the  term  was  used  to  signify 
the  policy  of  the  law,  might  be  "a  just  ground  for  judicial  decision," 
for,  "  it  amounts  to  no  more  than  that  a  contract  or  condition  is 
illegal  which  is  against  the  principles  of  the  established  law." 2  In 
fact,  a  body  of  law  like  the  common  law,  which  has  grown  up 
gradually  with  the  growth  of  the  nation,  necessarily  acquires  some 
fixed  principles ;  and,  if  it  is  to  maintain  these  principles,  it  must 
be  able,  on  the  ground  of  public  policy  or  some  other  like  ground, 
to  suppress  practices  which,  under  ever  new  disguises,  seek  to 
weaken  or  negative  them.3  Only  thus  can  it  maintain  the  essential 
continuity  of  its  principles.  At  the  same  time,  because  this 
principle  of  public  policy  gives  to  a  legal  system  the  power  of 
preserving  in  this  way  the  continuity  of  its  principles,  it  also  gives 
it  the  power  of  developing  its  principles  so  as  to  keep  them  in 
touch  with  the  needs  and  ideas  of  the  age.  It  thus  helps  to 
secure,  not  only  continuity,  but  also  a  certain  elasticity  in  the 
growth  of  the  law.  The  decision,  for  instance,  in  the  case  of 
Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society  4  would  have  been  as  unintelligible 
to  lawyers  of  an  earlier  age,  as  their  tolerance  of  traffic  in  offices 
of  trust 5  is  to  us. 

In  fact,  some  such  principle  is  an  almost  necessary  accom- 
paniment of  our  system  of  case  law,  and  gives  it  much  of  its 
effectiveness ;  for  it  makes  it  possible  for  the  judges  to  preserve 
the  continuity  of  legal  principles  and  at  the  same  time  to  keep  the 

1  Egerton  v.  Brownlow  at  p.  123. 

*  "  The  term  *  public  policy '  may  indeed  be  used  only  in  the  sense  of  the  policy  of 
the  law,  and  in  that  sense  it  forms  a  just  ground  of  judicial  decision.  It  amounts  to 
no  more  than  that  a  contract  or  condition  is  illegal  which  is  against  the  principle  of  the 
established  law.  If  it  can  be  shown  that  any  provision  is  contrary  to  well  decided 
cases,  or  the  principle  of  decided  cases,  and  void  by  analogy  to  them,  and  witbin  the 
same  principles,  the  objection  ought  to  prevail,"  ibid  at  pp.  123-124. 

s,,The  determination  of  what  is  contrary  to  the  so-called  'policy  of  the  law' 
necessarily  varies  from  time  to  time.  Many  transactions  are  upheld  now  by  our 
courts  which  a  former  generation  would  have  avoided  as  contrary  to  the  supposed 
policy  of  the  law.  The  rule  remains,  but  its  application  varies  with  the  principles 
which  for  the  time  being  guide  public  opinion,"  Evanturel  v.  Evanturel  (1874)  L.R.  6 
P.C.  at  p.  29  ;  "  rules  wr.ich  rest  upon  the  foundation  of  public  policy,  not  being  rules 
which  belong  to  the  fixed  or  customary  law,  are  capable,  on  proper  occasion,  of 
expansion  or  modification.  Circumstances  may  change  and  make  a  commercial 
practice  expedient  which  formerly  was  mischievous  to  commerce,"  Maxim  Nordenfelt 
Co.  v.  Nordenfelt  [1S93]  1  Ch.  at  p.  661  per  Bowen,  L.J. ;  these  dicta  were  approved 
by  Vaughan  Williams,  L.J.,  in  Wilson  v.  Carnley  [190S]  1  K.B.  at  pp.  737-73S — "  I 
cannot,"  he  said,  "  in  the  least  acquiesce  in  the  suggestion  that  as  habits  change  and 
time  goes  on,  we  may  not  find  new  instances  of  contracts  which  cannot  be  enforced  on 
the  ground  that  they  are  contrary  to  public  morality." 

4tIQI7]  A.C-.  406;  below  416.  5Vol.  i  250-251. 


56       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

law  in  touch  with  the  facts  and  needs  of  daily  life.1  No  doubt, 
in  its  application  to  the  law  of  contract,  we  must  remember  the 
epigram  of  Jessel,  M.R.,  to  the  effect  that  not  lightly  to  inter- 
fere with  freedom  of  contract  is  paramount  public  policy.2  But 
that  was  said  in  the  days  when  freedom  of  contract  was  supposed 
to  be  the  panacea  for  all  the  ills  of  the  body  politic.  It  represented 
a  passing  phase  of  political  thought ;  and  it  would  now  command 
as  much  and  as  little  assent  as  it  would  have  commanded  in 
the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  Historically,  complete 
freedom  of  contract  was  never  regarded  as  "paramount  public 
policy."  If  the  common  law  had  ever  taken  this  view  it  would, 
in  effect,  have  abandoned  its  valuable  concept  of  public  policy, 
and  have  thereby  lost  much  of  its  power  of  shaping  the  legal  and 
political  ideas  of  the  many  races  which  acknowledge  its  sway ;  for, 
as  Bowen,  L.J.,  truly  said,3  "the  interests  of  contracting  parties 
are  not  necessarily  the  same  as  the  interests  of  the  commonwealth." 

Because  the  common  law  has,  largely  through  its  system  of 
case  law,  kept  in  touch  with  the  needs  of  the  day,  it  is  a  little 
difficult  to  say  exactly  to  what  kinds  of  transaction  this  concept 
of  public  policy  was  first  applied.  In  the  sphere  of  contract  law 
it  has  been  said  that  it  was  first  applied  to  discourage  wagering 
contracts.4  In  truth,  it  is  much  older  than  this.  Long  before 
these  contracts  became  enforceable  through  the  development  of 
assumpsit,  it  had  been  applied  to  invalidate  transactions  which  ran 
counter  to  the  morality  of  the  day.  In  fact,  one  of  the  oldest  and 
one  of  the  most  continuous  of  its  applications  in  the  sphere  of 
contract  law  is  its  application  to  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade.5 
We  can  see  from  the  bulk  of  the  commercial  legislation  enacted 
at  all  periods  in  the  history  of  English  law,6  that  all  matters 
connected  with  trade  have  always  possessed  great  legal  and 
political  importance;  and  that  the  law  relating  to  them  has 
reflected  very  accurately  prevailing  political  and  economic  ideas.7 
It  is  not,  therefore,  surprising  to  find  that  the  law  as  to  contracts 
in  restraint  of  trade  has,  more  than  any  other  class  of  contracts, 
been  moulded  by  changing  ideas  of  public  policy. 

In  the  Middle  Ages,  when  the  object  of  the  Legislature  was 

1  See  Rodriguez  v.  Speyer  Bros.  [1919]  A.C.  at  pp.  79-81  per  Lord  Haldane. 

2  "  If  there  is  one  thing  which  more  than  another  public  policy  requires  it  is  that 
men  of  full  age  and  competent  understanding  shall  have  the  utmost  liberty  of  con- 
tracting, and  that  their  contracts  when  entered  into  freely  and  voluntarily  shall  be  held 
sacred  and  shall  be  enforced  by  courts  of  justice.  Therefore  you  have  this  paramount 
public  policy  to  consider  in  that  you  are  not  lightly  to  interfere  with  this  freedom  of 
contract,"  Printing  Co.  v.  Sampson  (1875)  19  Eq.  at  p.  465. 

:!  Maxim  Nordenfelt  Co.  v.  Nordenfelt  [1893]  *  Ch.  at  p.  661. 

4  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  380. 

8  See  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  221  (»). 

6  Vol.  ii  466-473  ;  vol.  iv  314-407  ;  vol.  vi  313-360. 

7  The  history  of  the  usury  laws,  below  100-112,  is  a  good  illustration. 


INVALIDITY  57 

the  attainment  of  ideally  fair  conditions  of  commerce  and  industry, 
when,  with  this  object  in  view,  their  conditions  were  minutely 
regulated  by  statutes  and  local  by-laws,1  any  attempt  to  disturb 
the  working  of  these  regulations  of  contract  was  regarded  almost 
as  a  crime.2  Such  an  attempt  was  akin  to  the  operations  of  the 
iniquitous  forestaller  and  regrator ;  and  there  is  little  doubt  that 
all  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade  were,  on  these  principles,  re- 
garded as  wholly  illegal.  But  we  have  seen  that,  during  the 
sixteenth  century,  political  and  moral  ideas  were  changing  as 
rapidly  as  the  conditions  of  trade ;  and  that  these  changes  neces- 
sarily produced  many  changes  in  men's  economic  ideas.3  The 
object  aimed  at  was  not  so  much  the  attainment  of  ideally  fair 
conditions  as  the  increase  in  national  power.  Traders  must  be 
encouraged  to  found  new  industries,  and,  with  that  object  in  view, 
new  associations  and  companies  must  be  founded,  in  order  that  the 
requisite  capital  might  be  provided.  Freer  play  must  be  left  to 
the  initiative  of  the  individual  trader  or  body  of  traders,  and 
therefore  to  their  power  to  make  what  contracts  they  pleased. 
Trade  was  not,  as  we  have  seen,  left  free  in  the  modern  sense.4 
As  in  the  Middle  Ages,  it  was  still  only  free  within  the  limits  not 
covered  by  regulation ;  and,  though  those  regulations  now  left  a 
wider  scope  to  the  activities  of  the  trader,  anything  which  infringed 
those  regulations  was  still  regarded  as  the  infringement  of  the 
freedom  of  trade  as  defined  by  law.  So  that,  just  as  a  monopoly 
which  infringed  the  freedom  of  trade  as  thus  understood  was 
illegal,5  so  a  contract  restraining  a  man  from  trading  must  be  for 
the  same  reason  held  to  be  void. 

Throughout  the  sixteenth  century  this  was  the  view  taken 
by  the  courts.  They  therefore  held  to  be  void  all  contracts  in 
restraint  of  trade.  Thus,  in  1578,  a  covenant  by  an  apprentice 
with  his  master  not  to  exercise  his  trade  in  Nottingham  for  four 
years,8  and  in  1587  a  covenant  not  to  exercise  the  trade  of 
blacksmith  in  Southmins  in  Surrey,7  were  held  to  be  void.  In 
1 602,  in  the  case  of  Colgate  v.  Bacheler*  it  was  resolved  that  it 
was  illegal  "to  prohibit  or  restrain  any  to  use  a  lawful  trade  at 
any  time  or  at  any  place  ;  for  as  well  as  he  may  restrain  him  for 
one  time  or  one  place,  he  may  restrain  him  for  longer  times  and 
more  places,  which  is  against  the  benefit  of  the  commonwealth  " ; 
and  Anderson,  C.J.,  remarked  that  a  man  "might  as  well  bind 

1  Vol.  ii  468-469. 

2  Y.B.  2  Hy.  V.  Pasch.  pi.  25  per  Hull,  J.,  cited  vol.  ii  468  n.  3. 

3  Vol.  iv  316-319,  324-326.  <  Ibid  350. 

5  Ibid  35o-353-  *  Anon.  Moore  115 

7  Anon,  ibid  242 ;  S.C.  2  Leo.  210. 
8Cro.  Eliza.  872  ;  S.C.  Owen  143. 


58       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

himself  that  he  would  not  go  to  church."1  This  remark  shows 
that,  as  in  the  Middle  Ages,  these  contracts  were  still  considered 
to  be  illegal,  because  they  attempted  to  vary  the  conditions  of 
trade  as  settled  by  law ;  and  in  all  of  them  the  dictum  of  Hull  in 
Henry  V.'s  Year  Book2  was  cited.  The  mediaeval  point  of  view 
was  still  predominant. 

But,  as  more  scope  was  given  to  the  individual,  as  he  therefore 
became  more  free  to  make  what  contracts  he  pleased,  it  began  to 
be  seen  that  this  rigid  rule  worked  injustice.  The  sale  of  a 
business  would  be  impossible,  if  the  vendor  could  at  once  set  up  a 
shop  next  door,  and  begin  to  compete  with  a  purchaser ;  and  it 
was  felt  to  be  hard  that  an  apprentice  could,  as  soon  as  he  had 
served  his  time,  use  all  his  former  master's  trade  secrets  to 
compete  with  him.  Therefore  contracts  imposing  a  limited 
restraint  of  trade  were  in  fact  made.  Consequently,  the  courts 
found  it  necessary  to  revise  their  attitude  to  them.  The  case  of 
Rogers  v.  Parry  in  16143  marks  the  beginning  of  this  change. 
In  that  case  the  defendant  had,  in  consideration  of  a  sum  of 
money  paid  by  the  plaintiff,  promised  the  plaintiff  that  he  would 
not  carry  on  the  trade  of  a  joiner  in  a  certain  shop,  during  the 
term  of  twenty-one  years  for  which  he  held  the  shop.  Coke,  C.J., 
pointed  out  that  this  was  not  a  contract  in  general  restraint  of 
trade;  and  the  whole  court  agreed  that,  "as  this  case  here  is  for 
a  time  certain  and  in  a  place  certain  a  man  may  well  be  bound 
and  restrained  from  using  of  his  trade  "  ;  and  this  view  of  the  law 
was  upheld  in  the  court  of  Exchequer  Chamber  in  1621  in  the 
case  of  Broad  v.  Jollyfe?  and  given  effect  to  in  several  contempor- 
ary and  subsequent  cases.5 

But  it  is  clear  that  these  cases  gave  only  a  very  carefully 
guarded  liberty  to  make  these  contracts.  They  only  established 
an  exception  to  the  general  rule  that  these  contracts  were  prima 
facie  illegal.  It  was  thus  necessary  to  define  the  conditions  under 
which  they  would  be  held  to  be  valid.  In  the  first  place,  it  was 
held  that  they  must  be  limited  as  to  space ;  and  they  were  at 
first  very  narrowly  limited.  Thus,  in  1668,  the  courts  were 
inclined  to  hold  that  a  covenant  not  to  set  up  a  trade  in  Cirencester 
was  void.6     In  the  second  place,  it  was  held  that  a  restraint  un- 

1  Owen  143  ;  cp.  the  Case  of  the  Tailors  of  Ipswich  (1615)  11  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  54a, 
where  an  ordinance  restricting  apprentices  in  their  trade  was  held  void  as  contrary 
to  the  Act  of  5  Elizabeth  c.  4  (see  vol.  iv  380  seqq.),  and  as  contrary  to  the  policy  of 
the  common  law. 

2  Cited  vol.  ii  468  n.  3.  32  Bulstr.  136.  4  Cro.  Jac.  596. 

5  Jelliet  v.  Broad  (1621)  Noy  98;  Bragge  v.  Stanner  (1622)  Palmer  172; 
Prugnell  v.  Gosse  (1649)  Alleyn  67  ;  Hunlocke  v.  Blacklowe  (1670)  2  Wms.  Sauuders 
156. 

6  Ferby  v.  Arrosmyth  2  Keble  377. 


INVALIDITY  59 

limited  as  to  space,  though  limited  as  to  time,  was  bad.1  In  the 
third  place,  no  restraint  could  be  justified  which  was  not  reasonable 
as  between  the  parties.  A  limited  restraint  imposed  on  the 
purchase  and  sale  of  a  business,2  or  by  a  master  on  his  apprentice,3 
might  be  justified.  But  there  must  not  only  be  a  sufficient 
consideration,  as  in  the  case  of  all  other  contracts,  but  a  considera- 
tion which  was  of  such  a  sort  that  it  proved  the  reasonableness  of 
the  transaction.4  Thus,  in  1685,  a  bond  taken  by  the  Company 
of  Tailors  at  Exeter  from  a  tailor  not  to  use  his  trade  in  Exeter ; 5 
and  in  1689  a  bond  not  to  buy  certain  goods  of  any  but  the 
plaintiff,  and  not  to  buy  more  than  a  certain  quantity,6  were  held 
to  be  void.  In  so  far  as  these  two  cases  decided  that  the  court 
could  not  enforce  such  a  contract  unless  it  was  reasonable  as 
between  the  parties,  they  were  no  doubt  rightly  decided.  But 
some  of  the  dicta  went  further.  Thus,  in  the  first  of  them  the 
analogy  of  the  infant's  bond  for  necessaries  was  used,  and  it  was 
held  that  a  bond  not  to  exercise  a  trade  was  in  no  circumstances 
good,  though  a  simple  contract  to  the  same  effect  might  be  good." 
We  have  seen  that  after  the  Revolution  there  was  a  tendency 
to  remove  many  of  the  old  restrictions  to  which  trade  had  formerly 
been  subject.  The  Whigs  were  backed  by  the  merchants  ;  and 
the  mercantile  opinion  which  favoured  freedom  of  trade  got  more 
weight  in  the  Legislature.8  It  was  inevitable  that  this  changed 
point  of  view  should  react  upon  the  courts,  and  that,  in  the  light 
of  it,  they  should  revise  their  views  as  to  the  validity  af  contracts 
in  restraint  of  trade.  In  fact,  at  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth 
century,  a  revision  of  the  law  on  this  topic  was  as  necessary  as  it 

1  See  Barrow  v.  Wood  (1643)  March  191,  where  serjeant  Evers  admitted  that, 
"if  a  man  binds  himself  not  to  use  his  trade  for  two  years,  or  if  a  husbandman  be 
bound  he  shall  not  plough  his  land,  these  are  conditions  against  law,  because  where 
the  restraint  is  total  .  .  .  the  condition  is  not  good  "  ;  cp.  the  Case  of  the  Tailors  oi 
Ipswich  (1615)  11  Co.  Rep.  53a. 

2,1  And  this  was  agreed  by  Rolle  for  law,  who  took  these  differences,  that  where 
a  bond  or  promise  restrains  the  exercise  of  a  trade,  although  it  be  as  to  a  particular 
place  only,  yet  if  it  be  upon  no  consideration,  the  bond  etc.,  is  void:  but  if  there 
were  a  consideration  for  the  restraint,  as  if  A  assign  a  shop  to  B  .  .  .  there  in 
respect  of  the  apparent  prejudice  which  may  accrue  to  B  if  A  should  continue  the 
trade,  such  a  bond  or  promise  is  good,"  Prugnell  v.  Gosse  (1649)  Alleyn  67. 

3  ,:  Windham  said  that  an  apprentice  might  be  bound  on  this  condition,  as  Hall 
against  Haws  9  Car.  1,  when  the  original  taking  and  instruction  is  on  these  terms," 
Ferby  v.  Arrosmyth  (1668)  2  Keble  377. 

4  Above  n.  2 ;  cp.  Jelliet  v.  Broad  (1621)  Noy  98  where  emphasis  was  laid  on 
the  adequacy  of  the  consideration ;  and  Clerk  v.  Taylors  of  Exeter  (1685)  3  Lev.  at 
p.  242. 

s  Clerk  v.  Taylors  of  Exeter  3  Lev.  241. 

6  Thompson  v.  Harvey  1  Shower  2. 

7  Clerk  v.  Taylors  of  Exeter  (1685)  3  Lev.  at  pp.  242-243  ;  and  the  same  rule 
was  laid  down  by  Reeve,  J.,  in  Barrow  v.  Wood  (1643)  March  at  p.  193  ;  but  opinions 
were  somewhat  conflicting,  see  Rolle's  opinion  cited  above  n.  2,  and  Dolben's  dis- 
senting opinion  in  Thompson  v.  Harvey  (1689)  1  Shower  at  p.  3. 

"Vol.  vi  333-334- 


60       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

had  become  at  the  end  of  the  nineteenth  century.  The  scattered 
cases,  which  had  begun  to  modify  the  older  rigid  principle,  con- 
tained the  germs  of  the  newer  law ;  but  they  were  not  wholly 
consistent,  and  some  laid  down  law  which  was  not  wholly  reason- 
able. It  was  obvious  that  they  all  required  to  be  reviewed  in  the 
light  of  the  new  economic  ideas  which  were  beginning  to  prevail. 
This  review  of  the  cases  and  restatement  of  the  law  was  made  in 
171 1  by  Parker,  C.J.  (the  future  Lord  Macclesfield),  whose  judg- 
ment in  the  case  of  Mitchel  v.  Reynolds x  is  the  true  beginning  of 
the  modern  law  on  this  subject. 

The  facts  in  the  case  of  Mitchel  v.  Reynolds  were  as  follows  : 
The  defendant  had  assigned  to  the  plaintiff  the  lease  of  a  bake- 
house in  the  parish  of  St.  Andrews,  Holborn,  for  the  term  of  five 
years,  and  had  given  a  bond  promising  to  pay  a  penalty  if,  during 
that  term,  he  exercised  the  trade  of  a  baker  in  that  parish.  The 
question  was  whether  this  bond  was  valid.  Parker,  C.J.,  pointed 
out  that  restraints  on  trade  might  be  either  involuntary,  that  is 
imposed  by  law  or  custom,  or  voluntary,  that  is  imposed  by  the 
agreement  of  the  parties.2  The  first  sort  were  restraints  imposed 
by  grants,  charters,  customs,  or  bye-laws ;  and  of  these  some,  e.g. 
a  grant  which  created  a  monopoly,  were  bad,  while  others,  e.g.  a 
bye-law  for  the  better  regulation  of  trade,  were  good.3  All  general 
restraints  imposed  by  the  agreement  of  the  parties,  and  all  restraints 
whether  general  or  particular  made  without  consideration,  were 
void.4  But  particular  restraints,  if  imposed  upon  a  good  and 
adequate  consideration,  "so  as  to  make  it  a  proper  and  useful 
contract"  5  were  good.  In  order  to  prove  this  thesis,  Parker,  C.J., 
made  a  novel  and  somewhat  unhistorical  use  of  the  analogy  of 
those  older  restraints  on  trade  imposed  by  the  law,  which  were 
then  beginning  to  be  regarded  as  obsolete.6  He  used  it  to  show 
that  the  law  had  never  indiscriminately  condemned  all  restraints 
on  trade,  pointing  out  that,  as  involuntary  restraints  had,  from  time 
immemorial,  been  imposed  by  custom,  they  must  have  had  a 
lawful  beginning."  But  these  involuntary  restraints  must  always 
have  been  reasonable,  so  that  even  a  crown  grant  which  attempted 
to  impose  an  unreasonable  restraint,  would  be  void.8  No  doubt  the 
reasons  which  induced  the  courts  to  hold  unreasonable  involuntary 


1 1  P.  Wms.  181.  2  Ibid  at  p.  183.  3  Ibid  at  pp.  183-185. 

4  Ibid  at  p.  185.  s  Ibid  at  p.  186.  6  Vol.  vi  337. 

7  "  Thirdly,  that  since  these  restraints  may  be  by  custom,  and  custom  must  have  a 
lawful  foundation,  therefore  the  thing  is  not  absolutely  and  in  itself  unlawful.  Fourthly, 
that  it  is  lawful  upon  good  consideration  for  a  man  to  part  with  his  trade.  Fifthly, 
that  since  actions  on  the  case  are  actions  injuriarum,  it  has  been  always  held  that  such 
actions  will  lie  for  a  man's  using  a  trade  contrary  to  custom,  or  his  own  agreement ; 
for  there  he  uses  it  injuriously,"  ibid  at  p.  187. 

8  Ibid  at  p.  183. 


INVALIDITY  61 

restraints  did  not  apply  to  voluntary  restraints  ; !  but,  as  both 
alike  were  restraints  on  trade,  this  difference  did  not  prevent  the 
law  from  treating  reasonable  voluntary  restraints  in  the  same 
way  as  reasonable  involuntary  restraints.  That  the  restraints 
should  be  reasonable  was  the  important  matter.  What  then  should 
be  the  test  of  reasonableness  ?  The  law  should  look  to  see  whether 
the  restraint  imposed,  either  a  restriction  on  the  party  which  would 
prevent  him  from  earning  his  livelihood,  or  a  hardship  on  the  public 
by  depriving  it  of  the  abilities  of  one  of  its  members.2  More 
especially  should  it  look  to  see  that  these  contracts  do  not  facilitate 
the  operations  of  those  corporations,  "  who  are  perpetually  labour- 
ing for  exclusive  advantages  in  trade,  and  to  reduce  it  into  as  few 
hands  as  possible  "  ; 3  or  the  operations  of  "  masters  who  are  apt 
to  give  their  apprentices  much  vexation  on  this  account,  and  to  use 
many  indirect  practices  to  procure  such  bonds  from  them,  lest  they 
should  prejudice  them  in  their  custom  when  they  come  to  set  up 
for  themselves."4  If  none  of  these  evils  appeared  to  be  likely  to 
result  from  a  contract  stipulating  for  a  particular  restraint,  it  was 
reasonable  and  valid,5  even  though  the  contract  took  the  form  of  a 
bond.6  But  the  onus  of  proving  that  it  has  satisfied  these  tests  of 
reasonableness  is  always  on  the  party  seeking  to  enforce  it,  and,  if 
he  cannot  satisfy  that  onus,  it  is  void  ;  for  the  law  always  presumes 
these  contracts  to  be  void." 

This  case  stands  at  the  parting  of  the  ways.  In  the  play 
which  it  makes  with  the  older  regulations,  depending  on  crown 
grants  customs  and  bye-laws,  we  can  see  traces  of  methods  of  con- 
trolling trade  which  had  fast  been  weakening  ever  since  the 
Revolution  ;  and,  in  the  manner  which  it  uses  the  analogy  afforded 
by  the  control,  which  the  common  law  exercised  over  the  reason- 
ableness of  these  regulations,  we  can  see  a  skilful  adaptation  of  the 
principles  underlying  this  control,  to  those  new  voluntary  restraints 
which  the  greater  freedom  accorded  to  trade  was  making  increas- 
ingly common.  The  control,  which  formerly  was  applied  to  the 
older  involuntary  restraints,  must  be  adapted  to  the  more  modern 
voluntary  restraints.  And  some  adaptation  was  necessary,  both 
because  the  control  of  these  voluntary  restraints  could  not  be 
justified  on  quite  the  same  grounds,  and  because  new  tests  of 
reasonableness  must  be  supplied.  It  is  in  the  definition  of  these 
new  tests  that  this  case  lays  down  substantially  modern  law.     No 

1 "  The  true  reason  of  the  disallowance  of  these  (voluntary  restraints)  in  any  case 
is  never  drawn  from  Magna  Charta ;  for  a  man  may  voluntarily  and  by  his  own  act 
put  himself  out  of  his  possession  of  his  freehold.  .  .  .  Neither  is  it  a  reason  against 
them  that  they  are  contrary  to  the  liberty  of  the  subject ;  for  a  man  may,  by  his  own 
consent,  part  with  his  liberty  ;  as  in  the  case  of  a  covenant  not  to  erect  a  mill  upon  his 
own  lands,"  i  P.  Wms.  at  pp.  188-189. 

*  Ibid  at  p.  100.  J  Ibid.  *  Ibid. 

5  Ibid  at  pp.  191,  197.  *  Ibid  at  pp.  194-196.  7  Ibid  at  pp.  191-192. 


62      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

doubt  changes  in  economic  conditions  have  rendered  some  of  the 
dicta  contained  therein  obsolete.  No  doubt  certain  expressions 
are  misleading  and  have  misled — the  use  throughout  the  case  of 
the  term  consideration,  both  in  its  technical  sense,  and  in  a  non- 
technical sense  to  mean  a  reasonable  ground  for  making  a 
contract,1  was  the  foundation  of  erroneous  ideas  as  to  the  part 
which  consideration  played  in  relation  to  these  contracts.2  No 
doubt  the  leading  principles  there  laid  down  were  somewhat 
obscured  by  the  detailed  rules,  and  fine  distinctions,  which  were 
elaborated  by  the  long  line  of  cases  which  followed  it.3  But,  when 
all  deductions  have  been  made,  there  is  no  doubt  that  we  see  in 
this  case  the  same  principles  which  were  restated,  and  applied  to 
a  new  economic  environment,  in  Nordenfelt  v.  the  Maxim  Norden- 
felt Co.,4  in  Mason  v.  the  Provident  Clothing  Co.?  and  in  Morris  v. 
Saxelby.^  All  these  decisions  follow  this  case  in  recognizing  that 
contracts  in  restraint  of  trade  are  prima  facie  void.  The  first 
recognizes  pre-eminently  the  principle  that  they  must  not  be 
injurious  to  the  public.  The  other  two  that  they  must  not  be 
oppressive  to  the  party  restrained.  In  fact,  the  two  main  evils 
pointed  out  by  Parker,  C.J.,  as  likely  to  result  if  these  contracts 
were  not  carefully  controlled — the  danger  of  allowing  a  great  cor- 
poration to  get  too  exclusive  a  control  of  trade,  and  the  danger 
that  masters  would  oppress  their  apprentices — precisely  correspond 
to  the  two  sets  of  circumstances  in  which  these  contracts  are 
usually  made.  They  are  usually  made,  either  on  the  purchase 
and  sale  of  a  business,  or  on  the  engagement  of  an  employee ;  and, 
as  the  modern  cases  show,  it  is  the  first  of  these  dangers  which 
must  be  specially  guarded  against  in  the  former,  and  the  second 
in  the  latter  type  of  case. 

Impossibility. 

The  parties  to  a  contract  may  either  (i)  promise  something 
absolutely  impossible  in  itself  or  made  impossible  by  law ;  or  (ii) 
something  not  inherently  impossible,  but  impossible  in  fact ;   or 

1  See  especially  i  P.  Wms.  at  pp.  192-193  where  consideration  is  used  (1)  in  the 
sense  of  evidence  of  reasonableness,  and  (2)  is  compared  with  the  consideration  in  a 
covenant  to  stand  seised. 

2  "  It  was  laid  down  in  Mitchel  v.  Reynolds  that  the  court  was  to  see  that  the  re- 
striction was  made  upon  a  good  and  adequate  consideration,  so  as  to  be  a  proper  and 
useful  contract.  But  in  time  it  was  found  that  the  parties  themselves  were  better 
judges  of  that  matter  than  the  court,  and  it  was  held  to  be  sufficient  if  there  was  a 
legal  consideration  of  value  ;  though  of  course  the  quantum  of  the  consideration  may 
enter  into  the  question  of  the  reasonableness  of  the  contract,"  Nordenfelt  v.  Maxim 
Nordenfelt  Co.  [1894]  A.C.  at  p.  565  per  Lord  Macnaghten  ;  see  1  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.) 
404-405,  and  Hitchcock  v.  Coker  (1837)  6  A.  and  E.  at  pp.  456-457  per  Tindal,  C.J. 

3  A  good  account  will  be  found  in  the  note  to  this  case  in  1  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.)  402 
seqq.  ;  and  in  the  judgments  in  Nordenfelt  v.  Maxim  Nordenfelt  Co.  [1894J  A.C.  535, 
especially  Lord  Macnaghten's  criticism  of  the  views  of  Bowen,  L.J.  at  pp.  562  seqq. 

4 [1894]  A-C  535-  5  [1913]  A.C.  724.  6  [1916]  1  A.C.  688. 


INVALIDITY  63 

(iii)  the  object  of  the  contract  may  be  made  impossible  by  the  act 
of  one  of  the  parties  to  the  contract.  The  last  named  case  is 
really  one  of  the  ways  in  which  a  contract  may  be  discharged  by 
breach,  and  I  shall  speak  of  it  under  that  head1 

(i)  As  to  promises  which  are  absolutely  impossible  in  them- 
selves there  is  not  much  authority.2  Probably  a  contract,  in 
which  such  a  stipulation  was  the  consideration  for  a  promise,  would 
be  held  to  be  void  because  there  was  in  fact  no  real  consideration.8 
But  such  promises  have  sometimes  come  before  the  courts  in  the 
shape  of  conditions  in  bonds.  A  promises  B  to  pay  a  sum 
certain,  with  a  condition  that,  if  a  certain  event  happens,  the 
promise  to  pay  is  to  be  void.  What  is  intended  is  to  secure  the 
happening  of  the  event ;  and  "  when  the  condition  is  illegal  our 
courts  have  found  no  difficulty  in  considering  the  bond  as  what  in 
truth  it  is,  an  agreement  to  do  the  illegal  act  But  in  the  case  of 
impossibility  the  law  has  stuck  at  the  merely  formal  view  of  a 
bond  as  a  contract  to  pay  the  penal  sum,  subject  to  be  avoided 
by  the  performance  of  the  condition ;  accordingly,  if  the  condition 
is  impossible  either  in  itself  or  in  law,  the  obligation  remains 
absolute."4  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  condition  is  subsequently 
made  impossible  of  performance  by  the  act  of  God,  or  if  one  of 
several  conditions  is  thus  made  impossible,  the  bond  becomes  void.5 

If  a  stipulation  in  a  contract  is  legally  impossible  of  perform- 
ance it  is  tantamount  to  saying  that  its  performance  is  illegal,  and 
therefore  void.  Thus,  where  the  bailiff  of  J.S.  promised  the 
defendant  that  he  would  release  a  debt  due  from  the  defendant  to 
J.S.,  if  the  defendant  would  repair  his  barge,  the  contract  was  held 
to  be  void  because  the  consideration  was  legally  impossible,  "for 
the  plaintiff  cannot  discharge  a  debt  due  to  his  master."  6 

(ii)  The  mere  fact  that  a  promise  is  impossible  in  fact  is  no 
ground  of  invalidity,  if  an  unconditional  promise  has  been  made." 

1  Below  78.  3  See  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  309. 

3  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  357. 

4  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  335  ;  Co.  Litt.  206b  (there  cited)  says,  "  If  a  man 
be  bound  in  an  obligation  etc.  with  condition  that  if  the  obligor  do  go  from  the  church 
of  St.  Peter  in  Westminster  to  the  church  of  St.  Peter  in  Rome  within  three  hours, 
that  then  the  obligation  shall  be  void.  The  condition  is  void  and  impossible,  and  the 
obligation  standeth  good." 

5  "  Where  a  condition  of  a  bond  consists  of  two  parts  in  the  disjunctive,  and  both 
are  possible  at  the  time  of  the  bond  made,  and  afterwards  one  of  them  becomes  im- 
possible by  the  act  of  God,  the  obligor  is  not  bound  to  perform  the  other  part :  for  the 
condition  is  made  for  the  benefit  of  the  obligor,  and  shall  be  taken  beneficially  for  him, 
and  he  hath  election  to  perform  the  one  or  the  other  for  the  saving  of  the  penalty  of  his 
bond  :  and  when  one  part  is  become  impossible  by  the  act  of  God,  it  is  as  beneficial 
for  him  as  if  that  part  of  the  disjunctive,  which  is  become  impossible,  had  been  only 
the  condition  of  the  bond,"  Laughter's  Case  (1595)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  22a ;  Pollock, 
Contracts  335. 

6  Harvey  v.  Gibbons  (1676)  2  Lev.  161. 

7"  En  tiels  cases  ou  nul  defaut  est  en  le  obligee  en  le  performance  del  condicion, 
en  ceux  cases  si  la  condicion  ne  soit  performe,  l'obligor  forfeitera,  come  en  case  si 


64      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

This  principle  is  well  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Paradine  v.  Jane} 
In  that  case  the  plaintiff  sued  the  defendant  for  three  years  arrears 
of  rent.  The  defendant  pleaded  that  Prince  Rupert  had  kept  him 
out  of  possession  from  July,  1643,  till  March,  1646,  so  that  he  could 
not  take  the  profits.  It  was  held  that  this  plea  was  no  answer  to 
the  action.  "  And  this  difference  was  taken,  that  when  the  law 
creates  a  duty  or  charge,  and  the  party  is  disabled  to  perform  it 
without  any  default  in  him,  and  hath  no  remedy  over,  then  the 
law  will  excuse  him.  As  in  the  case  of  waste,  if  a  house  be 
destroyed  by  tempest  or  by  enemies,  the  lessee  is  excused.  .  .  . 
But  when  the  party  by  his  own  contract  creates  a  duty  or  charge 
upon  himself,  he  is  bound  to  make  it  good,  if  he  may,  notwith- 
standing any  accident  by  inevitable  necessity,  because  he  might 
have  provided  against  it  by  his  contract."  This  is  still  the  law  if 
the  contract  is  in  terms  unconditional.  And  at  this  period  the 
courts  were  the  more  ready  to  apply  it  to  all  contracts,  because,  as 
we  shall  see,  they  were  inclined  to  hold  that  where  the  two  parties 
to  a  contract  made  mutual  promises,  those  promises  were  indepen- 
dent of  each  other,  so  that  each  could  sue  the  other  for  the  breach 
of  the  other's  promises,  whether  or  not  the  party  suing  had 
performed  his  part.2  We  shall  see  that  later  the  tendency  was  the 
other  way,  and  the  courts  were  more  inclined  to  hold  that  such 
promises  were  dependent  the  one  upon  the  other,  so  that  non- 
performance by  one  party  was  an  excuse  for  non-performance  by 
the  other.3  But  this  enabled  more  attention  to  be  paid  to  the 
underlying  intention  of  the  parties  when  they  entered  into  the 
contract,  and  so  made  it  possible  to  hold  that  they  were  excused 
by  the  happening  of  events  which  neither  had  contemplated  at 
that  date.4  This  has  led  to  numerous  exceptions  which  have,  to  a 
large  extent,  eaten  up  the  original  rule.  The  original  rule  is  now 
only  applicable  in  cases  where  the  parties  have  used  words  which 
show  that  they  intended  their  promises  to  be  absolute. 

The  alteration  of  a  contract  under  seal. 

It  was  laid  down  in  Pigot's  Case 5  that,  if  a  deed  is  altered 
in  a  material  point,  either  by  a  party  to  it  or  by  a  stranger,  the 
deed  becomes  void.  If  it  is  altered  in  an  immaterial  point  by 
a  party  to  it,  it  likewise  becomes  void  ;  but  if  it  is  altered  in  an 

home  soit  oblige  a  un  auter  en  xxli,  sur  condicion  quod  pluvia  debet  pluere  eras,  et 
sinon  donques  l'obligation  sera  bon,  en  eel  cas  si  pluvia  non  pluit  eras,  le  obligor  for- 
feitera  son  obligation  et  uncore  nul  defaut  fuit  en  luy,  car  il  ne  scavoit  que  pluvia  non 
debet  pluere,  mez  pur  ce  que  l'obligor  fuit  oblige,  et  nul  defaut  fuit  en  le  obligee  en  le 
performance,  pur  eel  cause  il  avera  son  accion  ;  en  meme  le  maner  si  home  soit  oblige 
a  moy  sur  condicion  que  le  Pape  sera  icy  a  Westmonesteris  in  crastino,  en  eel  cas  si  le 
Pape  ne  vient,  uncore  n'est  nul  defaut  en  le  defendant,  et  uncore  il  ad  forfeit  le 
obligacion,"  Y.B.  22  Ed.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  6  (p.  26)  per  Brian,  C.J. 

1  (1648)  Aleyn  26.  2  Below  72-73.  3  Below  73. 

*  Pollock,  Contracts  279.  5(i6i5)  n  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  27a. 


INVALIDITY  65 

immaterial  point  by  a  stranger  without  the  privity  of  the  party, 
the  deed  is  not  avoided.  These  rules  laid  down  by  Coke  are  the 
foundation  of  the  present  law  applicable  to  all  written  contracts.1 

Statutory  Provisions. 

The  two  statutes  affecting  the  validity  of  contracts  of  which  I 
intend  to  speak  at  this  point  are  the  statute  of  Frauds s  and  the 
statute  of  Limitation.3  Of  the  first  I  need  say  little  as  I  have 
already  discussed  the  effect  of  the  two  sections — the  fourth  and 
the  seventeenth — which  affect  the  validity  of  contracts.4  We 
have  seen  that  the  question  whether  the  fourth  section  rendered 
the  contract  void,  or  left  it  valid  but  unenforceable  by  action,  was 
for  some  time  doubtful ;  but  that,  before  the  point  was  actually 
decided,  the  better  opinion  was  that  it  only  rendered  the  contract 
unenforceable.5  We  have  seen  too  that  the  question  as  to  the 
effect  of  the  seventeenth  section  was  never  finally  decided.6  On 
the  other  hand,  it  was  reasonably  clear  from  the  words  of  James  I.'s 
statute  of  Limitation  that  that  statute  affected,  not  the  right  under 
a  contract,  but  the  right  to  enforce  it.  As  the  court  said  in  the 
case  of  Wainfordv.  Barker?  "it  is  a  debt  tho'  barrable  by  pleading 
of  the  Statute." 

(2)  The  different  effects  of  these  various  causes  of  invalidity. 

It  will  be  clear  that  these  various  causes  of  invalidity  produced 
very  different  effects  upon  contracts.  They  might  render  them 
either  void,  voidable,  or  unenforceable  by  action.  It  is  clear  that,  as 
early  as  1 55 1,  the  courts  were  well  aware  of  the  difference  between 
void  and  voidable  transactions — indeed  it  was  clearly  brought  out 
by  the  rules  as  to  the  different  manner  in  which  it  was  necessary 
to  plead  these  two  facts.  "  The  statute  saith  '  if  an  obligation  be 
taken  in  other  form  than  is  contained  in  the  statute  it  shall  be 
void,'  and  from  what  time  shall  it  be  void?  I  say,  from  the 
beginning,  and  if  it  be  void  from  the  beginning,  then  it  never  was 
his  deed,  and  if  it  never  was  his  deed,  then  he  ought  to  have  con- 
cluded non  est  factum.  As  if  a  man  will  plead  in  avoidance  of  a 
deed  that  he  was  a  man  not  lettered,  and  that  the  deed  was  read  to 
him  in  other  form  .  .  .  then  he  ought  to  conclude,  non  est  factum, 
because  the  matter  proves  that  it  never  was  his  deed.  But,  if  it 
was  once  his  deed,  and  afterwards  the  duty  thereof  became  extinct, 
then  he  ought  to  demand  judgment  si  actio.  .  .  .  As  if  an  infant 
or  a  man  by  duress  make  an  obligation,  they  shall  demand  judgment 

1  Sea  Master  v.  Miller  (1791)  4  T.R.  at  p.  330  per  Lord  Kenyon,  C.J. 

*  29  Charles  II.  c  3.  s  21  James  I.  c.  16  §  3  ;  vol.  iv  533. 

*  Vol.  vi  390-393.  5  Above  35. 

*  Vol.  vi  386  n.  4.  7  (1698)  1  L<L  Raym.  232. 
VOL.  VIlT. — 5 


66       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

si  actio,  because  the  delivery  of  the  deed  was  not  void.  And 
so  is  the  diversity  when  a  man  shall  say  non  est  factum,  and  when 
he  shall  demand  judgment  si  actio."  1  Or,  to  translate  these  differ- 
ences from  the  phraseology  of  adjective  to  the  phraseology  of 
substantive  law,  so  is  the  diversity  between  void  and  voidable. 
Similarly,  it  is  clear  from  the  manner  in  which  the  courts  inter- 
preted the  statute  of  Limitation,  and  the  fourth  section  of  the 
statute  of  Frauds,  that  they  had  a  clear  enough  appreciation  of  the 
practical  consequences  of  the  differences  between  void  and  unen- 
forceable. 

But,  though  the  courts  have  shown  a  clear  enough  appreciation 
of  these  essential  differences,  both  they  and  the  Legislature  have 
often  used  the  terms  void,  voidable,  and  unenforceable  very  loosely. 
The  word  void  is  often  used  where  either  voidable  or  unenforceable 
is  meant.  Thus,  the  incorrect  term  "  void  "  was  applied  to  infants' 
contracts  instead  of  the  correct  term  "voidable,"  before  certain  of 
these  contracts  had  really  been  made  void  by  the  Infants'  Relief 
Act ; 2  and  the  same  term  was  sometimes  applied  to  contracts 
which  were  not  evidenced  by  writing  as  required  by  section  four 
of  the  statute  of  Frauds.3  So  that,  as  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  truly  said, 
"  the  language  of  text  writers,  of  judges,  and  even  of  the  Legislature, 
is  no  safe  guide  apart  from  the  actual  decisions."4  We  shall,  I 
think,  find  the  explanation  of  this  curious  phenomenon  in  the  fact 
that  these  differences  were  worked  out  mainly  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  procedure  and  pleading  in  an  action.  The  fact  that 
they  were  so  worked  out  is  illustrated  clearly  enough  by  the 
extract  from  the  case  of  Dive  v.  Manningham  just  cited.5  We 
have  seen,  too,  that  the  best  evidence  of  the  fact  that  the  effect  of 
non-compliance  with  section  four  of  the  statute  of  FYauds  was  to 
render  the  contract  unenforceable,  is,  firstly,  the  manner  in  which 
the  courts  allowed  a  memorandum,  drawn  up  after  the  contract 
had  been  made,  to  be  given  in  evidence  ;  and,  secondly,  the  growth 
of  the  equitable  doctrine  of  part  performance.6  Both  these  rules 
really  originate  in  rulings  as  to  the  evidence  admissible  to  prove 
the  contract.  Similarly  the  long  controversies  as  to  whether  it 
was  necessary  to  plead  specially  the  statute  of  Limitation,7  would 
hardly  have  been  possible,  if  the  courts  had  not  been  conscious 
that  the  statute  affected,  not  the  validity,  but  the  enforceability, 
of  the  contract. 

1  Dive  v.  Manningham,  Plowden  at  p.  66  per  Mountague,  C.J. ;  as  we  have  seen 
there  was  Year  Book  authority  for  these  propositions,  above  51  n.  3. 

2  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  59-60. 

3  See  e.g.  Birkmyr  v.  Darnell  (1705)  1  Salk.  at  p.  28. 

4  Contracts  (5th  ed.)  54.  5  Above  65-66. 
8  Above  35  ;  vol.  vi  393,  658-659. 

7  See  ncte  6  to  Hodsden  v.  Harridge  2  Wms.  Saunders  63. 


INVALIDITY  67 

Now,  if  a  judge  is  trying  an  action,  and  a  defendant  pleads  a 
plea  which  is  an  answer  to  the  plaintiff's  claim,  the  result  upon  the 
issue  of  that  action  is  the  same  whether  the  effect  of  the  plea  is  to 
make  the  contract  void,  voidable,  or  unenforceable.  Whether  the 
plea  is  non  est  factum,  or  infancy,  or  the  statute  of  Limitation,  the 
result  upon  the  action  of  the  proof  of  the  plea  is  the  same — the  plain- 
tiff loses.  Hence,  if  the  matter  is  looked  at  solely  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  result  of  the  particular  case  before  the  court,  it  is  very 
easy  to  slide  into  a  loose  way  of  characterising  the  contract,  which 
a  plaintiff  is  seeking  in  vain  to  enforce.  It  is  easy  to  call  it  void, 
when  voidable  or  unenforceable  is  meant,  because,  whichever  word 
is  used,  the  result  to  the  plaintiff  is  the  same  ;  and  when  once  this 
loose  manner  of  talking  has  become  habitual  to  judges  and  lawyers, 
it  is  bound  to  affect  the  phraseology  of  text-books  and  statutes, 
which  are  written  or  drafted  by  those  same  lawyers.1 

That  this  explanation  of  this  confusion  in  phraseology  is  true, 
is  the  more  probable  if  we  consider  that  the  greater  part  of  our  law 
of  contract  has  grown  up  in  the  atmosphere  of  procedure.  The 
origin  and  growth  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration  is,  as  we  have 
seen,  one  striking  illustration  of  this  fact.  We  shall  see  other 
illustrations  of  this  fact  in  the  manner  in  which  the  law  originally 
dealt  with  the  effects  upon  a  contract  of  fraud  and  misrepresenta- 
tion, and  in  many  of  the  rules  relating  to  the  enforcement  of  con- 
tracts, and  to  their  discharge  by  breach. 

(3)  The  effects  of  fraud  and  misrepresentation. 

In  modern  law  fraud  and  misrepresentation  are  usually  classed 
among  the  facts  which  may  affect  the  validity  of  a  contract.  But 
it  was  long  before  they  came  to  be  regarded  from  this  point  of 
view.2  Fraud,  as  we  have  seen,  was  a  tort;  and  in  the  Middle 
Ages  it  had  been  developed  by  an  action  of  deceit  on  the  case.3 
It  was  only  by  bringing  such  an  action  that  a  fraud  (whether  in- 
ducing a  contract  or  not)  could  be  remedied ;  and  there  was  no 
remedy  for  misrepresentation  not  amounting  to  fraud.  For  the 
growth  of  such  a  remedy,  and  for  the  growth  of  the  idea  that  fraud, 
and  in  certain  cases  misrepresentation,  may  operate  to  invalidate 
a  contract,  and  may  give  rise  to  remedies  on  the  contract,  we  must 
look  to  a  development  in  the  remedies  provided  for  frauds  induc- 
ing a  contract. 

Both  the  action  of  deceit  and  the  action  of  trespass  on  the  case 
played  their  part  in  the  development  of  the  action  of  assumpsit.4 

1  For  an  instance  where  the  Legislature  used  the  term  "  void  "  when  it  meant 
"voidable  "  see  Re  Carter  and  Kenderdine's  Contract  [1897]  1  Ch.  776. 

2  For  the  early  interference  of  the  chancellor  owing  to  this  defect  in  the  common 
law,  see  vol.  v  292,  326,  328. 

3  Vol.  iii  407-408.  *  Ibid  407-408,  429  n.  3, 


68       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

We  have  seen  that  in  Somertoris  Case  it  was  held  that  a  lawyer 
who  had,  in  breach  of  his  undertaking,  betrayed  his  employer  and 
acted  for  his  rival,  could  be  made  liable  in  an  action  of  deceit  on 
the  case.1  It  was  no  long  step  to  take  to  hold  that,  if  a  person 
definitely  and  expressly  warranted  the  truth  of  certain  facts,  and 
the  facts  turned  out  to  be  otherwise,  he  could  also  be  made  liable 
to  an  action  of  deceit  on  the  case.2  In  other  words,  he  could  be 
made  liable  in  tort  for  a  false  warranty  ;  and,  if  he  had  thus 
warranted  the  truth  of  certain  facts,  he  could  be  made  liable  for 
the  damage  resulting  from  their  untruth,  whether  or  not  he  knew 
them  to  be  untrue.3  It  followed,  therefore,  that  if  a  contract  was 
induced  by  fraud  or  misrepresentation  the  party  aggrieved  had  no 
remedy  by  action  on  the  contract ;  for  the  contract  was  not  thereby 
rendered  invalid.  But  he  had  an  action  in  tort  for  deceit  if  he 
could  prove  that  the  other  contracting  party  knew  that  his  repre- 
sentation was  false,4  or  if  at  the  time  of  the  contract  he  had 
expressly  warranted  its  truth.5 

It  was  with  reference  to  contracts  for  the  sale  of  goods  that 
these  principles  were  almost  exclusively  developed  ; 6  and  it  is  one 
of  these  cases — the  case  of  Chandelor  v.  Lopus  " — which  shows 
most  clearly  the  attitude  of  the  law  at  the  beginning  of  the 
seventeenth  century.  In  that  case  the  plaintiff  brought  an  action 
on  the  case  against  the  defendant  a  jeweller,  for  that  he,  "being  a 
jeweller,  and  having  skill  in  jewels  and  precious  stones,  had  a 
stone  which  he  affirmed  to  be  a  Bezoar  stone,  and  sold  to  the 
plaintiff  for  one  hundred  pounds ;  ubi  re  vera  it  was  not  a  Bezoar 
stone."  The  plaintiff  got  a  verdict  in  the  King's  Bench  ;  "  but 
error  was  thereof  brought  in  the  Exchequer  Chamber ;  because 
the  declaration  contains  not  matter  sufficient  to  charge  the 
defendant,  viz. :  that  he  warranted  it  to  be  a  Bezoar  stone,  or  that 
he  knew  that  it  was  not  a  Bezoar  stone ;  for  it  may  be  that  he 
himself  was  ignorant  whether  it  were  a  Bezoar  stone  or  not  "  ;  and 
on  this  ground  the  judgment  was  reversed.  As  it  was  clear  that 
there  had  been  no  warranty,  the  plaintiff  then  brought  a  fresh  action, 
alleging  that  the  defendant  knew  the  stone  not  to  be  a  Bezoar 
stone.8     Whether  this  declaration  disclosed  a  good  cause  of  action 

iVol.  iii  431-432. 

2  Bellewe  139-140,  citing  a  Y.B.  of  7  Rich.  II.  concerning  a  warranty  of  a  horse, 
cited  vol.  iii  408  n.  1. 

3  Ibid  40S  and  n.  2. 

*  Dale's  Case  (1586)  Cro.  Eliza.  44  ;  Sprigwell  v.  Allen  (1649)  Aleyn.  91. 

8  Roswell  v.  Vaughan  (1608)  Cro.  Jac.  at  p.  197  ;  Rolle,  Ab.  Action  stir  Case  P. 
pi.  4  (i  p.  90),  and  see  ibid  i  g7  pi.  1,  citing  a  case  of  33  Eliza. 

"As  Mr.  Street  had  said,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  i  377,  "the  proper 
approach  to  the  subject  of  fraud  in  its  modern  aspects  is  found  in  the  law  of  chattel 
sales." 

7  (1603)  Cro.  Jac.  4. 

8  From  a  MS.  volume  of  reports  in  the  Harvard  Law  School  Library  printed 
H.L.R.  viii  282-284. 


INVALIDITY  69 

divided  the  court,  and  the  ultimate  issue  of  the  action  is  not 
known.1  But  it  is  clear  from  this  case  that  a  defendant,  induced 
to  contract  by  fraud,  had  no  remedy  except  in  tort ;  and  that  he 
could  only  succeed  in  an  action  of  tort  if  he  could  prove  that  the 
defendant  either  knew  that  his  statements  were  untrue,  or  he  had 
expressly  warranted  -  their  truth  at  the  time  of  the  making  of  the 
contract.3  The  only  exceptions  to  this  rule  were  the  cases  of  sales 
of  food  and  drink,  which  the  law  required  to  be  pure,  and  to  which 
there  was  therefore  annexed  an  implied  warranty  of  quality.4 

It  would  seem  that  the  judges,  dreading  to  encourage  litigation 
by  disappointed  purchasers,  were  inclined  to  insist  very  strictly 
on  the  maxim  ' '  caveat  emptor."  5  If  a  man  sells  an  unsound  horse 
or  unsound  wine,  "it  behoveth,"  says  Fitzherbert,6  "that  he 
warrant  the  wine  to  be  good  and  the  horse  to  be  sound,  other- 
wise the  action  will  not  lie.  For  if  he  sell  the  wine  or  horse 
without  such  warranty,  it  is  at  the  other's  peril,  and  his  eyes  and 
his  taste  ought  to  be  his  judges  in  that  case."  This,  in  effect,  left 
the  law  without  any  adequate  means  of  repressing  fraud.  Its 
definition  of  fraud  was  too  narrow,  in  that  it  did  not  include 
statements  made  recklessly ;  and  it  took  no  account  of  statements 
made  at  the  time  of  a  sale,  which  in  fact  amounted  to  a  warranty, 
unless  they  were  put  into  the  form  of  an  express  warranty."  But 
it  is  obvious  that,  in  one  respect,  the  idea  that  a  man  might  be 
liable  in  tort  for  the  breach  of  an  express  warranty,  tended  to 
develop  the  law.  This  liability  for  breach  of  warranty,  though 
asserted  by  an  action  in  tort,  existed  whether  or  not  the  person 
warranting  knew  of  its  falsity.  In  fact,  the  ground  of  the  liability 
was  as  much  contractual  as  delictual ;  for  it  was  based  on  the 
breach  of  the  warranty  as  to  the  truth  of  the  statement  warranted. 

1  It  may  perhaps  be  inferred  from  the  statement  of  counsel  in  Southern  v.  How 
(1618)  Cro.  Jac.  at  p.  469  that  the  second  action  succeeded ;  he  says  distinctly  that 
"  because  that  it  was  sciens  the  plaintiff  had  judgment  "  ;  this  statement  was  not  con- 
tradicted, and  Tanfield,  J.,  had  said,  H.L.R.  viii  284,  "  it  is  agreed  by  all  that  if  in 
this  case  sciens  le  defendant  were  omitted,  the  plaintiff  could  not  recover." 

2  "  Note  that  by  the  civil  law  every  man  is  bound  to  warrant  the  thing  that  he 
selleth  and  conveyeth,  albeit  there  be  no  express  warranty :  but  the  common  law 
bindeth  him  not  unless  there  be  a  warranty  either  in  deed  or  in  law,  for  Caveat 
Emptor,"  Co.  Litt.  102a. 

s  Andrew  v.  Boughey  (1553)  Dyer  at  ff.  75b,  76a  ;  in  the  case  of  Pope  v.  Lewyns 
(1622)  Cro.  Jac.  630  it  was  held  that  the  proper  form  of  declaration  was  warranti- 
zando  vendidit  not  warrantizavit  et  vendidit ;  cp.  Mew  v.  Russell  (1683)  2  Shower  284. 

4  Vol.  iii  386  ;  Street,  op.  cit.  i  379-380. 

s  "  This  case  is  a  dangerous  case  and  may  be  the  cause  of  a  multitude  of  actions, 
if  it  be  thought  that  the  bare  affirmation  of  the  vendor  causes  the  action,"  Chandelor 
v.  Lopus  H.L.R.  viii  284  per  Popham,  C.J. 

•F.N.B.  94c;  cp.  Tanneld,  J.'s  views,  H.L.R.  viii  284. 

^Street,  op.  cit.  i  379-380;  and  see  Popham,  C.J.'s  views  H.L.R.  viii  284;  as 
Mr.  Street  says,  "  Between  the  two  propositions  that  there  can  be  no  warranty  with- 
out an  express  agreement,  and  no  fraud  without  an  actual  knowledge  of  the  falsity  of 
the  representation,  the  ingenious  rascal  went  free." 


70      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

This    clearly  tended    to    introduce  into  the  law   the   idea   that 
non-fraudulent  misrepresentation  might  be  a  ground  of  liability. 

It  was  not  till  the  eighteenth  century  that  the  liability  of 
vendors  for  mis-statements,  fraudulent  or  otherwise,  was  extended 
by  the  growth  of  the  idea  that  a  warranty  could  be  implied. 
This  development  took  place,  first  in  relation  to  warranty  of  title,1 
and  later  and  less  completely  in  respect  of  warranties  of  quality. 
When,  towards  the  close  of  the  eighteenth  century,  it  became 
possible  to  sue  for  damages  for  breach  of  a  warranty  by  an  action 
on  the  contract,2  it  became  clear  that  fraud,  and  certain  kinds  of 
non-fraudulent  misrepresentation,  had  a  direct  effect  upon  the 
validity  of  a  contract.  In  fact,  as  Mr.  Street  has  truly  said,3  since 
then  "  the  law  of  warranty  has  been  transferred  almost  bodily  to 
the  domain  of  contract."  When  that  happened,  the  ideas  which 
originated  in  the  law  of  warranty  as  applied  to  sales  of  goods, 
during  the  period  when  the  action  on  a  warranty  was  an  action  in 
tort,  were  applied  to  other  classes  of  contract.4  As  the  result  of 
this  development,  it  will  become  possible  to  regard  fraud,  and 
certain  kinds  of  non-fraudulent  misrepresentation,  as  having  definite 
effects  upon  the  validity  of  a  contract.  But  the  law  had  not 
reached  this  point  at  the  close  of  the  seventeenth  century.  The 
only  remedy  for  a  false  representation  was  an  independent  action 
in  tort ;  and,  as  we  shall  see  in  the  following  sections,  the  rules  as 
to  the  enforcement  of  contracts,  and  as  to  their  discharge  by  failure 
of  performance,  were  such  that  it  would  hardly  have  been  possible 
for  a  person  who  had  been  defrauded  to  get  adequate  relief  by  an 
action  on  the  contract. 

Enforcement 

Both  the  rules  as  to  quid  pro  quo,  and  the  doctrine  of  con- 
sideration, presuppose  the  fact  that  both  the  parties  to  a  contract 
have  duties  thereunder.  If,  therefore,  one  of  the  parties  to  a 
contract  wishes  to  compel  the  other  to  perform  his  duties  under  it, 

1  The  first  advance  in  this  direction  was  made  by  Holt,  C.J.'s  decisions  in  Crosse 
v.  Gardner  (1689)  Carth.  90,  and  Medina  v.  Stoughton  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  593,  to 
the  effect  that  an  affirmation  by  a  seller  in  possession  of  goods  that  they  were  his 
own  amounts  to  a  warranty  ;  as  Mr.  Street  says,  op.  cit.  i  383,  this  decision  tended 
to  "  brea'<  down  the  rule  that  express  words  of  warranty  are  necessary." 

2  The  first  reported  case  in  which  this  was  allowed  was  Stuart  v.  Wilkins  (1778) 
1  Dougl.  18  ;  but  according  to  Buller  and  Ashhurst,  JJ.,  ibid  at  p.  21,  the  practice 
of  so  declaring  was  considerably  older,  though  it  evidently  struck  Lord  Mansfield  as 
a  novelty. 

3  Op.  cit.  i  390. 

4  At  this  period  there  are  very  few  examples  of  the  application  of  this  remedy 
except  in  the  case  of  contracts  of  sale  ;  one  of  the  few  cases  is  Anon.  (1683)  Skin.  119, 
where  the  plaintiff  sued  the  defendant  for  deceit  in  pretending  to  be  a  single  person, 
and  inducing  her  to  go  through  the  form  of  marriage  with  him  ;  cp.  Street,  op.  cit.  i 
392. 


ENFORCEMENT  71 

the  question  arises  whether  he  can  do  so  if  he  has  not  himself 
performed  his  own  duties.  It  is  clear  that  on  this  question  three 
possible  views  may  be  taken.  Firstly,  A's  right  to  enforce  B's 
duty  under  a  contract,  made  between  A  and  B,  may  be  conditional 
upon  A's  performance  of  his  own  duty ;  or  A's  and  B's  duties 
may  be  regarded  as  being  entirely  independent  of  each  other,  so 
that  each  can  sue  the  other,  though  the  party  suing  has  not 
performed  his  part ;  or  A's  and  B's  duties  may  be  regarded  as 
being  due  simultaneously,  so  that  neither  can  sue  the  other,  unless 
the  party  suing  is  ready  and  willing,  at  the  time  of  the  action 
brought,  to  perform  his  duty.1 

The  rules  applicable  to  this  question  are,  at  the  present  day, 
regarded  as  depending  on  the  interpretation  of  the  intention  of  the 
parties  to  the  contract.  "The  court  looks  to  the  purpose  and 
effect  of  the  contract  as  a  whole  as  a  guide  to  the  probable 
intentions  of  the  parties,  and  the  presumption,  if  any  there  be,  is 
that  breach  or  default  in  any  material  term  of  a  contract  between 
men  of  business  amounts  to  default  in  the  whole."  -  But  this 
was  not  so  clearly  the  attitude  of  the  court  in  the  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth  centuries.  The  rules  on  this  subject  were  still  im- 
plicated with,  and  influenced  by,  the  forms  of  action  by  which 
contracts  were  enforced ;  and  though,  no  doubt,  the  courts 
attempted  to  ascertain  the  intention  of  the  parties,  both  the 
procedural  rules,  and  the  tendency,  which  has  already  been  noted 
in  dealing  with  the  interpretation  of  conveyances,3  to  lay  down 
rigid  rules  of  construction,  combined  to  make  the  law  on  this 
topic  one  of  the  most  technical  and  least  satisfactory  parts  of  the 
law  of  contract. 

As  the  growth  of  the  law  on  this  topic  during  this  period 
was  largely  influenced  by  the  development  of  the  forms  of  action, 
I  shall  consider,  firstly,  the  rules  which  grew  up  in  the  spheres 
of  debt  and  covenant,  and  their  modification  when  they  came  to 
be  applied  in  the  sphere  of  assumpsit ;  and,  secondly,  the  rules 
which  originated  in  the  need  to  distinguish  the  spheres  of  special 
assumpsit  and  assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit* 

(i)  The  rules  which  grew  up  in  the  spheres  of  debt  ami 
covenant,  and  their  ?nodification  when  they  catne  to  be  applied  in 
the  sphere  of  assumpsit. 

We  have  seen  that  the  right  to  bring  an  action  of  debt  was 
conditional  upon  the  gift  of  a  thing  or  the  doing  of  an  act  by 

1  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  280. 

2  Ibid  279.  *  Vol.  vii  392-394. 

*  For  an  account  of  the  sphere  of  these  different  forms  of  action  see  vol.  iii  417- 
426,  428,  429  seqq.,  446,  447. 


72       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

the  plaintiff,  which  would  be  regarded  as  quid  pro  quo  for  the 
defendant's  promise;  and  that,  except  in  the  case  of  the  contract 
of  sale  of  goods,  a  mere  promise  to  give  or  perform  was  not  a 
sufficient  quid  pro  quo.1  It  followed  that  the  plaintiff  could  not 
recover  unless  he  had  performed  his  side  of  the  bargain ;  and 
we  have  seen  that  the  same  rule  resulted  from  the  conditions 
under  which,  at  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  action 
of  assumpsit  lay  for  nonfeasance  in  breach  of  an  undertaking; 
for,  till  assumpsit  was  extended  to  remedy  the  breach  of  wholly 
executory  contracts,  the  detriment  suffered  by  the  plaintiff  on 
the  faith  of  the  defendant's  promise  must  have  been  actually 
incurred.2  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  case  of  the  contract  of 
sale  of  goods,  the  duty  to  pay  and  the  duty  to  transfer  were 
regarded  as  independent  obligations,  so  that  each  could  sue 
the  other  for  failure  to  perform,  whether  or  not  he  had  fulfilled 
his  part  of  the  bargain — "contracts  of  debt,"  as  Vaughan,  C.J., 
said,  "are  reciprocal  grants."3  The  same  reasoning  was  applied 
to  the  reciprocal  covenants  of  the  parties  in  a  contract  under 
seal.  This  fact  is  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Ware  v.  Chappel.* 
Ware  had  by  deed  covenanted  with  Chappel  that  he  would 
provide  five  hundred  soldiers  and  bring  them  to  a  certain  port, 
and  Chappel  had  covenanted  to  provide  shipping  and  victual 
for  them.  Ware  sued  Chappel  for  not  providing  the  shipping 
and  victual  at  the  appointed  time,  and  Chappel  pleaded  that 
Ware  had  not  raised  the  soldiers  at  that  time.  Rolle,  C.J., 
held  that  this  plea  was  no  answer  to  the  action,  because  "  they 
are  distinct  and  mutual  covenants,  and  there  may  be  several 
actions  brought  for  them."  He  then  pointed  out  that  Chappel  had 
his  remedy  against  Ware  if  he  raised  not  the  men,  as  Ware  had 
against  Chappel  for  not  providing  the  shipping.  Under  these 
circumstances  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  the  mutual  promises 
which,  at  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century  had  come  to  be 
enforceable  by  assumpsit,  were  treated  in  the  same  way.  This 
fact  is  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Gower  v.  Capper  (i 597).5  In 
that  case  the  defendant  owed  the  plaintiff  ^20.  The  defendant, 
in  consideration  of  a  promise  to  deliver  up  the  bill  evidencing 
the  debt,  promised  to  give  two  sufficient  sureties  for  the  payment 
of  the  £20.  The  plaintiff  sued  the  defendant,  alleging  that  he 
had  delivered  up  the  bill,  but  that  the  defendant  had  broken 
his  promise  by  producing  two  worthless  sureties.  The  defendant 
pleaded  that  the  plaintiff  had  not  delivered  up  the  bill.  The 
plaintiff  demurred,  and  judgment  was  given  for  him,   "  for  the 

1  Vol.  iii  420-423.  2  Ibid  441,  442. 

3  Edgcomb  v.  Dee  (1670)  Vaughan  at  p.  101. 

4  (1649)  Style  186.  6  Cro.  Eliza.  543. 


ENFORCEMENT  73 

alleging  that  he  had  delivered  the  bill  was  but  surplusage;  for 
the  consideration  was  the  promise  to  deliver  it ;  .  .  .  a  promise 
against  a  promise  is  a  sufficient  ground  for  an  action."  The 
same  rule  was  applied  in  other  seventeenth-century  cases.1 

But  these  were  only  prima  facie  rules.  The  courts  were 
always  willing  to  give  effect  to  any  expressions  used  by  the 
parties  which  indicated,  or  seemed  to  indicate,  their  intentions 
as  to  the  order  in  which  the  mutual  undertakings  of  the  parties 
were  to  be  performed.  If  it  could  be  gathered  that  the  per- 
formance by  one  was  a  condition  precedent  to  performance  by 
the  other,  the  other  could  resist  an  action  until  performance  had 
been  made.2  On  the  other  hand,  if  performance  by  one  was 
not  a  condition  precedent,  each  could  sue  the  other,  whether  or 
not  he  had  performed  his  part  of  the  agreement.3  In  the  first 
case  the  promises  were  said  to  be  dependent,  and  in  the  second 
independent  But  the  rules  applied  to  determine  whether,  in 
any  given  case,  a  promise  was  dependent  or  independent,  were 
so  technical  and  artificial  that  it  was  almost  impossible  to  deduce 
from  them  any  certain  principle.*  As  Williams  says,  after  citing 
a  number  of  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  century  cases,  "the  judges 
in  these  cases  seem  to  have  founded  their  construction  of  the 
independency  or  dependency  of  covenants  or  agreements  on 
artificial  and  subtle  distinctions,  without  regarding  the  intent 
and  meaning  of  the  parties."5  As  usually  happens  in  these 
cases,  the  ingenuity  of  the  judges  resulted  in  the  establishment 
of  a  number  of  very  artificial  rules  of  construction,  which  hindered 
rather  than  helped  the  elucidation  of  the  intention  of  the  parties 
in  any  given  case.6  They  had  an  effect  upon  the  interpretation 
of  the  duties  of  the  parties  to  a  contract  similar  to  the  equally 
artificial  rules  for  the  interpretation  of  conveyances,  which  those 
same  judges  were  constructing  at  this  period7 

In  fact,  so  long  as  the  judges  considered  that  the  promises 
to  be  performed  by  the  two  parties  to  a  contract  must  be  either 

1  Pordage  v.  Cole  (1669)  1  Wms.  Saunders  319,  and  the  cases  cited  in  the  note 
thereto. 

1  Rogers  v.  Snow  (1573)  Dal.  94  ;  Brocas's  Case  (1588)  3  Leo.  219  ;  Everard  v. 
Hopkins  (1615)  1  Rolle  Rep.  at  p.  125  per  Coke,  C.J. ;  Spanish  Ambassador  v.  Gifford 
(1616)  1  Rolle  Rep.  336  ;  Trench  v.  Trewin  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  124. 

3  Nichols  v.  Raynbred  (1615)  Hob.  88 ;  and  see  the  cases  from  1  Rolle  Rep. 
cited  in  the  last  note. 

4  "  Almost  all  the  old  cases,  and  many  of  the  modern  ones  on  this  subject, 
are  decided  on  distinctions  so  nice  and  technical,  that  it  is  very  difficult,  if  not 
impracticable,  to  deduce  from  them  any  certain  rule  or  principle  by  which  it  can 
be  ascertained  what  covenants  are  independent,  and  what  dependent,"  1  Wms. 
Saunders  320  n. 

8  ibid. 

•For  these  rules   see  ibid;    Thorpe  v.  Thorpe   (1702)    1   Ld.    Raym.   at  pp. 
664-667 ■ ;  and  the  notes  to  Cutter  v.  Powell  2  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.)  10-16. 
7  Vol.  vii  394. 


74       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

dependent  or  independent,  it  was  really  impossible  to  avoid  hard- 
ship. It  was  as  hard  on  a  plaintiff  to  force  him  to  perform  as 
a  condition  of  recovery,  as  it  was  on  a  defendant  to  require  him 
to  perform  in  spite  of  the  plaintiffs  failure  to  perform.1  It  was 
only  natural  that,  while  the  law  was  in  this  state,  the  arguments 
of  plaintiffs  and  defendants  should  be  directed  chiefly  to  this 
simple  point  of  proving  dependency  or  independency ;  and  that, 
as  cases  argued  on  these  lines  accumulated  the  rules  as  to  what 
promises  were  dependent  and  what  independent  should  grow 
more  and  more  subtle  and  unsatisfactory.  It  is  clear,  too,  that, 
so  long  as  the  question  was  regarded  from  this  point  of  view,  it 
was  difficult  to  decide  in  accordance  with  the  substantial  merits 
of  the  case,  and  to  give  effect  to  the  real  intentions  of  the  parties 
to  any  given  contract.  Thus,  for  instance,  it  is  difficult  to  see 
how  any  effect  could  be  given  to  such  defences  as  fraud  or  mis- 
representation. If  the  promises  were  dependent,  a  plaintiff, 
though  defrauded,  could  not  hope  to  recover  unless  he  could 
prove  performance ;  and  if  they  were  independent,  the  fact  that 
he  had  defrauded  the  defendant  would  be  no  answer  to  his  action. 
At  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century  the  courts  began 
to  perceive  that  it  was  impossible  to  class  all  stipulations  in 
contracts  as  dependent  or  independent.  They  began  to  see  that 
in  many  cases  contracts  consisted  of  "mutual  conditions  to  be 
performed  at  the  same  time  "  2 — in  other  words,  that  conditions 
might  be  concurrent  This  was  recognized  in  17 14,  in  the  case  of 
Tumor  v.  Goodwin?  where  there  was  a  contract  to  pay  money  for 
the  assignment  of  a  judgment  debt.  Parker,  C.J.,  said,4  "the 
question  is  whether  the  plaintiffs  assignment  be  the  first  act  to  be 
done  or  not.  This  differs  fiom  the  other  cases  where  the  time  and 
the  consideration  are  mentioned.  The  defendant  would  have 
assigning  to  be  first  assigning,  and  the  plaintiff  would  have  it 
assigning  .  .  .  after  payment.  We  are  all  of  opinion  that  there 
is  one  way  which  will  solve  all  these  difficulties,  and  that  is  the 
assignment  shall  neither  precede  nor  wait,  but  shall  accompany 
the  payment,  and  both  to  be  done  at  the  same  time.  .  .  .  The 
money  is  here  his  security  till  the  assignment ;  though  the  money 
be  told  over  by  the  defendant  and  plaintiff,  yet  it  remains  the 
defendant's  money,  and  the  plaintiff  cannot  justify  the  taking  it 
though  laid  on  the  table.  On  the  other  hand,  the  moment  he  has 
delivered  the  assignment,  the  property  of  the  money  is  altered.  .  .  . 
'Tis  like  buying  of  goods,  this  money  is  yours  if  you  deliver  to 

1  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  136 ;  Mr.  Street  at  pp.  132-140 
has  given  a  good  account  of  this  branch  of  the  law  to  which  I  am  much  indebted. 

'JThis  is  the  expression  used  by  Lord  Mansfield,  C.J.,  in  Kingston  v.  Preston 
(1772),  cited  in  Jones  v.  Barkley  (1773)  2  Dougl.  at  p.  691. 

3  Fortescue  145.  4  At  pp.  149-150. 


ENFORCEMENT  75 

me  this  watch  ;  the  money  is  his  if  he  deliver  the  watch,  if  not  'tis 
otherwise." 

To  these  concurrent  conditions  neither  the  rules  applicable  to 
dependent,  nor  those  applicable  to  independent  promises,  were 
applicable.  It  was  therefore  laid  down  that  in  these  cases,  "  if  one 
party  was  ready  and  offered  to  perform  his  part,  and  the  other 
neglected  or  refused  to  perform  his,  he  who  was  ready  and  offered 
has  fulfilled  his  engagement,  and  may  maintain  an  action  for  the 
default  of  the  other ;  though  it  is  not  certain  that  either  is  obliged 
to  do  the  first  act"1  This  tended  to  diminish  the  importance  of 
the  older  cases,  which  laid  down  rules  as  to  when  the  promises  of 
the  parties  were  dependent,  and  when  they  were  independent  It 
became  more  possible  to  pay  attention  to  the  real  intention  of  the 
parties  to  the  contract ;  and  to  develop  rules  as  to  their  respective 
rights  and  duties,  based  upon  their  performance  of  or  failure  to 
perform  their  contract  When,  therefore,  towards  the  close  of  the 
eighteenth  century,  the  rules  as  to  the  method  of  treating  these 
concurrent  conditions  in  a  contract  were  settled,  the  courts  began  to 
see  that  the  older  rules  as  to  when  a  condition  or  promise  should 
be  treated  as  dependent  and  when  as  independent,  were  too  rigid 
and  technical ;  and  they  therefore  began  to  lay  it  down  that  these 
matters  must  be  decided  by  "  the  good  sense  of  the  case."  -  In 
other  words,  the  expressions  used  by  the  parties  to  a  contract  must 
be  construed  in  order  to  discover  their  intentions,  and  effect  must 
be  given  to  the  intention  thus  discovered.  With  the  adoption  of 
this  changed  attitude  by  the  courts  of  law,  the  modern  history  of 
this  branch  of  the  law  begins. 

(2)  TJie  rules  which  originated  in  the  need  to  distinguish  the 
spheres  of  special  assumpsit  and  assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit 

We  have  seen  that  these  two  branches  of  the  action  of  assumpsit 
became  distinct  in  the  course  of  the  seventeenth  century,  and  that 
practical  consequences  were  drawn  from  these  differences.3  Thus 
we  have  seen  that  it  was  settled  in  1696  that  indebitatus  assumpsit 
would  only  lie  where  a  debt  had  been  incurred,  and  that  therefore 
it  would  not  lie  on  an  executory  contract  where  a  promise  was 
consideration  for  a  promise.4     It  followed  that  if  two  parties  made 

1  Kingston  v.  Preston  (1773)  2  Dougl.  at  p.  691. 

s "  In  ordinary  cases  of  this  kind  the  work  is  to  be  done  before  the  wages  are 
earned  ;  but  those  cases  do  not  apply  to  the  present,  where  both  the  acts  are  to  be  done 
at  the  same  time.  Speaking  of  conditions  precedent  and  subsequent  in  other  cases 
only  leads  to  confusion.  In  the  case  of  Campbell  v.  Jones,  I  thought,  and  still  continue 
to  be  of  that  opinion,  that  whether  covenants  be  or  be  not  independent  of  each  other, 
must  depend  on  the  good  sense  of  the  case,  and  on  the  order  in  which  the  several 
things  are  to  be  done,"  Morton  v.  Lamb  (1797)  7  T.R.  at  p.  130  per  Lord  Kenyon,  C.J. 

5  Vol.  iii   446-447. 

4Bovey  v.  Castleman  1  Ld.  Raym.  ot,;  Smith  v.  Aiery  (1705)  6  Mod.  128. 


76      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

a  contract,  and  the  performance  of  one  was  a  condition  precedent 
to  payment  by  the  other,  the  former  could  not  sue  the  latter  either 
by  action  of  debt  or  indebitatus  assumpsit,  or  by  action  of  special 
assumpsit,  if  he  could  not  allege  and  prove  performance.  He  could 
not  sue  by  action  of  debt  or  indebitatus  assumpsit  because  the 
debt  was  not  incurred.  Thus  when  A  was  employed  by  B  to 
collect  his  rents,  and  B  promised  to  pay  him  ^iooa  year,  and  B 
died  after  A  had  acted  for  three  quarters  of  a  year,  it  was  held  that 
A  could  recover  nothing  from  B's  executor  by  action  of  debt.1  It 
is  clear  also  that  he  could  recover  nothing  by  special  assumpsit, 
because  the  promise  to  pay  was  in  consideration  of  his  service  for 
a  year,  and  such  performance  he  could  not  allege.  He  could  only 
have  recovered  the  value  of  his  services  if  the  testator  had  wrong- 
fully broken  his  contract ;  for  in  that  case  the  special  contract 
would  not  be  in  existence,  and  he  would  therefore  have  been  in  the 
position  of  one  who  had  done  something  of  value  for  another,  not 
under  or  in  fulfilment  of  a  special  contract.  In  such  a  case  the 
law  would  have  implied  a  promise  to  pay  what  his  services  were 
reasonably  worth,  for  which  he  could  have  sued  by  indebitatus 
assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit.2 

These  rules  as  to  the  conditions  under  which  special  assumpsit 
and  assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit  lay,  gave  rise  to  the  rule, 
which  was  clearly  laid  down  in  1795  in  the  case  of  Cutter  v. 
Powell.*  In  that  case  the  defendant  promised  to  pay  a  sailor  thirty 
guineas,  if  he  "  proceeded  continued  and  did  his  duty"  as  second 
mate  on  a  voyage  from  Jamacia  to  Liverpool.  He  died  on  the 
voyage,  and  it  was  held  that  his  representatives  could  not  recover 
on  a  quantum  meruit.  "  That  where  the  parties,"  said  Lord 
Kenyon,  C. J.,  "  have  come  to  an  express  contract  none  can  be 
implied,  has  prevailed  so  long  as  to  be  reduced  to  an  axiom  in 
the  law."4  This  is  still  the  law,  if  it  is  clear  that  no  payment  is 
due  till  the  whole  of  the  consideration  for  that  payment  has  been 
performed.5  But  the  need  to  distinguish  between  cases  of  this 
kind,  to  which  the  rule  applies,  and  cases  in  which  the  parties 
have  varied  their  contract,  or  have  in  fact  accepted  something 
not  quite  in  accordance  with  it,  have  given  rise  to  many  compli- 
cated rules,  and  to  "  distinctions  more  than  usually  fine."  6 

The  circumstances  under  which  the  special  contract  is  re- 
scinded, so  that  a  person  who  has  performed  services  under  it  is 
entitled  to  sue  on  a  quantum  meruit,  falls  under  the  next  follow- 
ing topic — discharge  of  contract. 

1  Countess  of  Plymouth  v.  Throgmorton  (1688)  1  Salk.  65. 

2  Vol.  Hi  447.  :i  6  T.R.  320.  4  Ibid  at  p.  324. 

5  Pollock,  Contracts  (9th  ed.)  285.  6  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.)  16  seqq. 


DISCHARGE  77 

Discharge 

The  three  ways  in  which  contract  may  be  discharged,  with 
which  I  propose  to  deal,  are,  breach ;  performance  or  the  tender 
thereof;  and  agreement 

(i)  Breach. 

It  follows  from  what  has  been  already  said  as  to  the  enforce- 
ment of  contracts,  that  the  modern  rules  applicable  to  the  breach 
of  contract  by  failure  of  performance,  were  not  ascertained  during 
this  period.  If  the  promises  of  the  two  parties  were  independent 
of  each  other,  failure  of  performance  by  one  was  not  a  discharge 
of  the  other's  obligation.  If  they  were  dependent,  the  plaintiff 
must  prove  performance  on  his  side,  and  it  was  only  then  that  he 
could  sue  for  damages  if  the  other  party  failed  to  perform.  In 
such  a  case  there  could  be  no  question  of  the  right  of  the  plaintiff 
to  rescind  the  contract,  according  to  whether  the  failure  of  per- 
formance went  to  the  root  of  the  contract  or  not,  for  he  had 
already  performed  his  side  of  the  contract.  When,  however,  it 
came  to  be  recognized  that,  where  the  promises  of  the  two  parties 
were  concurrent,  either  might  sue  on  proof  that  he  was  ready  and 
willing  to  perform,  the  question  arose  whether  or  not  any  given 
failure  gave  the  right  to  rescind  the  whole  contract,  or  whether  it 
did  not  give  such  a  right ;  but  only  gave  a  right  to  sue  for  such 
damages*  as  had  been  sustained  by  the  failure.  It  is  in  this 
connection  that,  in  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries, 
the  modern  distinctions  between  conditions,  and  warranties,  and 
warranties  ex  post  facto,  grew  up.  These  expressions  were  used, 
often  inconsistently,  to  express  the  differences  between  those  terms 
in  a  contract  failure  to  perform  which  gave  rise  to  a  right  to 
rescind,  those  terms  which  did  not  give  this  right,  and  those  terms 
which  would  have  given  such  a  right  if  their  breach  had  not  been 
acquiesed  in.1 

But  failure  to  perform  a  contract  may  arise  from  many 
causes.  It  may  be  due,  for  instance,  to  fraud  or  misrepresenta- 
tion ;  and  we  have  seen  that  one  of  the  older  remedies  for  a 
fraudulent  misstatement,  which  induced  a  contract,  was  an  action 
in  tort  on  a  warranty,  if  an  express  warranty  had  been  given  at 
the  time  of  the  making  of  the  contract2  We  have  seen,  too,  that, 
in  the  eighteenth  century,  the  scope  of  this  remedy  was  enlarged 
by  the  growth  of  the  conception  of  an  implied  warranty  ;  and  that 
it  was  recognized  that  false  or  fraudulent  misstatements  which  in- 
duced a  contract  might  be  remedied  by  an  action  on  the  contract.3 

1  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  330-337. 

3  Above  68.  3  Above  68-70. 


78       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

In  effect,  the  result  of  such  misstatements  was  a  total  or  partial 
failure  of  performance ;  and  thus  it  comes  about  that,  in  our 
modern  law,  the  effect  of  fraud  upon  a  contract  is  treated  in  much 
the  same  way  as  the  breach  of  a  condition  which  amounts  to  total 
failure  of  performance,  and  gives  a  right  to  rescind ;  while  non- 
fraudulent  misrepresentation  is  treated,  according  to  the  nature  of 
the  fact  or  facts  misrepresented,  either  as  the  breach  of  a  condition 
which  amounts  to  total  failure  of  performance  and  gives  a  right  to 
rescind,  or  as  the  breach  of  a  warranty  which  amounts  to  a  partial 
failure  of  performance,  and  gives  only  a  right  to  get  damages  as 
compensation  for  its  breach. 

Other  cases  of  failure  of  performance,  which  cause  a  breach 
of  contract,  are  a  refusal  to  perform,  or  impossibility  of  performance 
created  by  one  of  the  parties  to  the  contract.  It  was  recognized 
in  this  period  that  both  put  an  end  to  the  contract,  and  gave  the 
party  injured  the  right  to  sue  for  damages  for  its  breach.  That 
a  refusal  to  perform  a  contract  amounts  to  a  breach  is  an  obvious 
truism.  That  it  was  recognized  as  a  truism  can  be  seen  from  the 
case  of  Lea  v.  Exelby}  In  that  case  the  defendant  was  possessed 
of  a  lease  for  years,  and  the  plaintiff  owned  the  reversion  upon  it. 
The  plaintiff  promised  to  pay  the  defendant  a  sum  of  money,  and 
the  defendant  promised,  on  payment,  to  surrender  the  lease.  The 
plaintiff  sued  the  defendant,  alleging  that  he  had  tendered  the 
money  and  that  the  defendant  had  not  surrendered.  It  was  held 
that  the  plaintiff  could  not  recover,  because  he  ought  to  have 
alleged,  either  that  he  had  paid  the  money,  or  that  he  had  both 
tendered  the  money  and  that  the  defendant  had  refused  it.  It 
was  the  refusal  which  constituted  the  breach  of  the  contract  for  which 
he  was  suing ;  and  as  refusal  had  not  been  alleged,  no  cause  of 
action  arose.  That  impossibility  of  performance  created  by  the 
act  of  one  of  the  parties  to  a  contract  amounts  to  a  breach  of  the 
contract  is  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Hulbert  v.  Watts?  where  the 
contrast  between  impossibility  so  occasioned,  and  that  occasioned 
by  the  act  of  God,  is  expressly  noted. 

(2)  Performance  or  the  tender  thereof. 

Performance  may  take  the  form  either  of  doing  an  act  or  of 
making  a  payment.  The  act  promised  must  be  completely  per- 
formed in  order  to  discharge  the  duty  under  the  contract ;  and 
this  was  a  rule  frequently  applied  in  cases  where  performance  was 
a  condition  precedent  to  the  right  to  enforce  the  fulfilment  of  the 
promise  of  the  other  party.  Thus  in  1619  a  judgment  for  a 
plaintiff  was  arrested,  because  he  failed  to  show  complete  per- 

1  (1602)  Cro.  Eliza.  888.  2  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  H2. 


DISCHARGE  79 

formance  of  his  duty  under  the  contract.1  A  payment  was  com- 
plete, so  that  the  money  was  at  the  risk  of  the  payee,  as  soon  as 
he  had  accepted  the  coins ; 2  and  it  was  a  valid  payment  if  the 
money  paid  was  legal  tender,  even  though  its  value  had  been  de- 
preciated by  the  act  of  the  crown,  so  that  in  that  case  the  payee 
must  stand  the  loss.3  One  of  the  rules  as  to  payment  illustrates 
a  further  advantage  which  assumpsit  had  over  debt.  If  money 
was  to  be  paid  in  instalments  spread  over  a  fixed  period,  debt 
would  not  lie  for  the  non-payment  of  each  instalment  as  it  came 
due,  but  it  could  only  be  brought  at  the  end  of  the  period,  "  because 
all  is  but  one  contract."  4  On  the  other  hand,  assumpsit  lay  for 
each  instalment  as  it  came  due.  Whether  or  not  repeated  actions 
could  be  brought  for  each  instalment  as  it  came  due,  or  whether, 
when  once  the  action  had  been  brought,  the  plaintiff  lost  all 
further  right  of  action,  was  a  matter  upon  which  the  courts  were 
much  divided.5  There  was  at  first  a  tendency  to  accept  the  latter 
view,  and  consequently  to  rule  that  the  plaintiff,  on  the  defendant's 
failure  to  pay  any  one  instalment,  could  get  damages  for  non- 
payment of  the  entire  debt6  But  the  other  and  the  more  sensible 
view  was  adopted  in  167 1."  It  was  then  settled  that,  "the  action 
might  be  brought  for  such  sum  of  money  only  as  was  due  at  the 
time  of  bringing  the  action,  and  the  plaintiff  should  recover 
damages  accordingly ;  and  when  another  sum  shall  become  due, 
the  plaintiff  may  commence  a  new  action  for  that  also,  and  so 
to  ties  quo  ties." 

Tender,  or  attempted  performance,  may  take  the  form  either 
of  a  tender  of  goods  or  of  money.  At  the  beginning  of  the  six- 
teenth century  a  plea  of  tender  did  not  discharge  a  defendant,  un- 
less he  pleaded,  not  only  that  he  had  offered  to  convey  or  pay,  but 
also  that  he  was  still  ready  to  do  so.8  But,  when  Coke  wrote,  the 
law  had  been  modified.  The  old  rule  was  still  applied  to  the  tender 
cf  money ;  and  this  is  still  the  law  ;9  but  in  the  case  of  the  tender 
of  goods  it  was  sufficient  to  plead  that  the  goods  had  been  offered, 
without  pleading  that  the  defendant  was  still  ready  to  deliver.10 

1  Leneret  v.  Rivet,  Cro.  Jac.  503. 

2  Canter  v.  Shepheard  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  330. 

3  Pong  v.  Lindsay  (1553)  Dyer  82a. 

4  "  If  I  sell  you  anything  for  £100  to  be  paid  £20  per  ann.  in  5  years,  I  shall  not 
have  an  action  for  debt  till  all  the  years  be  incurred,  because  all  is  but  one  contract," 
Foord's  Case  (1595)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  81b ;  cp.  Rudder  v.  Price  (1791)  1  H.  Bl.  547  ; 
a  good  historical  summary  of  this  topic  will  be  found  in  Lord  Loughborough's  judg- 
ment in  the  last  cited  case. 

5  In  Pecke  v.  Redman  (1556)  Dyer  113  the  judges  were  divided  on  the  question. 

6  Beckwith  v.  Nott  (1619)  Cro.  Jac.  504 ;  but  the  contrary  view  was  taken  in 
Milles  v.  Milles  (1632)  Cro.  Car.  241. 

7  Cooke  v.  Whorwood  2  Wms.  Saunders  337. 

8  Brikhed  v.  Wilson  (1537)  Dyer  24b.  »  Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  314. 
10  *'  If  an  obligation  of  an  hundred  pound  be  made  with  condition  for  the  payment 

of  fifty  pounds  at  a  day,  and  at  the  day  the  obligor  tender  the  money,  and  the  obligee 


80       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

The  effect  of  successfully  pleading  a  tender  of  money  was  that 
the  plaintiff  could  only  recover  the  amount  tendered ; x  and,  in 
Coke's  day,  if  he  refused  it  in  court  and  took  issue  on  the  tender, 
and  it  was  found  against  him,  he  lost  the  money  for  ever.2  On 
the  question  what  would  amount  to  a  valid  tender  the  law  had 
already  acquired  a  number  of  detailed  rules,  principally  in  connec- 
tion with  the  payment  of  rent.  These  rules  were  summarized  by 
Coke  in  Wades  Case,3  and  they  are  the  basis  of  the  modern  law. 

(3)  Agreement. 

We  have  seen  that  English  law  has  substantially  accepted  the 
Roman  rule,  repeated  by  Bracton,  that  a  contractual  obligation 
must  be  dissolved  by  the  same  formalities  as  those  by  which  it 
was  made.4  As  in  English  law  the  two  formalities  needed  for 
making  an  agreement  actionable  are  either  a  writing  under  seal,  or 
a  consideration,  it  follows  that  an  agreement  to  discharge  a  con- 
tract must  comply  with  one  of  these  two  forms.  But  the  law  has 
been  to  some  extent  complicated,  firstly,  by  the  fact  that  the  con- 
tract under  seal  has  always  been  regarded  as  a  contract  of  a  superior 
sort  to  the  simple  contract,  so  that,  though  a  contract  under  seal 
can  discharge  a  simple  contract,  the  converse  is  not  true ;  and, 
secondly,  by  difficulties  in  applying  the  doctrine  of  consideration 
to  the  discharge  of  simple  contracts — difficulties  which  have,  to  a 
large  extent,  been  caused  by  the  gradual  growth  of  that  doctrine, 
and  the  difficulty  of  reconciling  it,  in  its  developed  form,  with 
earlier  rules  as  to  the  discharge  of  simple  contracts  by  agreement. 
1  shall  therefore,  in  the  first  place,  deal  with  the  operation  of  the 
contract  under  seal  in  discharging  a  contract ;  and,  in  the  second 
place,  with  the  operation  of  a  simple  contract.  Lastly,  I  shall  say 
something  of  a  method  of  discharge  which  the  growth  of  the  simple 
executory  contract  made  possible — the  novation. 

(i)  The  operation  of  a  contract  under  seal  in  discharging  a 
contract. 

It  was  well  settled  in  the  sixteenth  century  that  a  release  under 
seal  would  discharge  either  a  contract  under  seal,  or  a  simple  con- 
tract. Thus  Coke  in  Pinnel's  Case  could  cite  Year  Book  authority 
for  the  proposition  that  an  acknowledgment  of  satisfaction  by  a 

refuseth  the  same,  yet  in  action  of  debt  upon  the  obligation,  if  the  defendant  plead 
the  tender  and  refusal,  he  must  also  plead  that  he  is  yet  ready  to  pay  the  money  and 
tender  the  same  in  Court.  ...  If  a  man  be  bound  in  200  quarters  of  wheat  for  de- 
livery of  100  quarters,  if  the  obligor  tender  at  the  day  100  quarters,  he  shall  not  plead 
uncore  prist,  because  albeit  it  be  parcel  of  the  condition  yet  they  be  bona  peritura%  and 
it  is  a  charge  for  the  obligor  to  keep  them,"  Co.  Litt.  207a. 

1  Pong  v.  Lindsay  (1553)  Dyer  82a,  b.  2  Co.  Litt.  207a. 

3(r6oi)  5  Co.  Rep.  114a.     '  4  Vol.  u  277  find  n.  10. 


DISCHARGE  81 

deed  would  discharge  a  contract  under  seal,  though  nothing  had 
been  received  in  satisfaction ; 1  and  Croke,  in  the  case  of  Acton  v. 
Symon,2  differing  from  Berkley,  J.,  laid  it  down  that,  if  the  two 
parties  to  a  simple  contract  afterwards  made  a  contract  under  seal 
to  the  same  effect,  the  simple  contract  was  discharged.3  The  fact 
that  the  law  has  always  given  effect  to  the  lawful  intentions  of  the 
parties  to  a  writing  under  seal,  and  the  fact  that  such  a  writing 
is  regarded  as  superior  to  a  mere  parol  contract  or  contract  made 
by  unsealed  writing,  has  prevented  any  question  arising  as  to  the 
efficacy  of  this  mode  of  discharging  any  contract.  We  shall  now 
see  that  the  fact  that  the  law,  from  these  two  points  of  view,  treated 
simple  contracts  very  differently,  has  resulted  in  raising  many  diffi- 
cult questions  as  to  their  operation  in  discharging  such  contracts. 

(ii)  The  operation  of  a  simple  contract  in  discharging  a  con- 
tract.,4 

In  the  first  place,  a  simple  contract  cannot  discharge  a  contract 
under  seal.  Coke's  assertion,  that  "it  appears  by  all  our  books 
that  neither  arbitrament  nor  accord  with  satisfaction  is  a  plea  when 
the  action  is  grounded  on  a  deed,"  5  was  well  warranted  by  the 
earlier  authorities.6  In  fact,  as  we  have  seen,  the  strictness  with 
which  the  law  adhered  to  the  view  that,  even  payment  was  no 
discharge  of  an  obligation  under  seal,  without  a  formal  release, 
was,  in  the  Middle  Ages,  a  frequent  cause  of  applications  to  the 
chancellor."  Apparently  there  was  some  disposition  to  relax  this 
strictness  at  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century  ; s  but  it  did  not 
go  far,  as,  shortly  afterwards,  the  rule  approved  of  by  Coke  was 

1 "  If  a  man  acknowledge  himself  to  be  satisfied  by  deed,  it  is  a  good  bar,  without 
anything  received,"  Pinnel's  Case  (1602)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  117b,  citing  Fitzherbert  Ab. 
Barre  pi.  37  (26  Hy.  VI.). 

2  (1636)  Cro.  Car.  414. 

*M  Berkley  said,  if  one  borrow  money,  and  promise  to  enter  into  bond  to  pay  it 
at  a  day  to  come,  and  promise  that  he  will  keep  his  day  of  payment,  and  afterwards 
he  makes  an  obligation  for  the  payment  of  this  money  at  the  day,  if  he  fail  of  the  pay- 
ment, debt  may  be  brought  against  him  upon  the  obligation,  and  he  may  also  maintain 
an  action  of  the  case  upon  the  promise ;  but  I  denied  it,  because  the  obligation  deter- 
mines the  contract,"  ibid  at  p.  415. 

4  See  generally  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  88-95. 

5  Blake's  Case  (1606)  6  Co.  Rep.  43b. 

•Y.BB.  45  Ed.  III.  Hil.  pi.  9;  1  Hy.  V.  Trin.  pi.  1  (p.  7) per  Hals. ;  1  Hy.  VII. 
Pasch.  pL  1  (p.  14)  where  Vavisor  says,  "  in  nul  cas  on  ne  poit  voider  un  obligation 
sans  especialty  de  aussy  haut  nature  que  le  fait  est";  Anon.  (1513)  Dyer  ia.  By 
"arbitrament "  Coke  means  the  judgment  of  arbitrators,  which,  as  Mr.  Street  says,  op. 
cit  ii  91,  "created  a  duty  in  the  nature  of  debt  like  the  judgment  of  a  court";  it 
therefore  operated,  like  an  accord  and  satisfaction,  to  discharge  a  simple  contract,  see 
below  84  n.  4. 

7  Vol.  v  292. 

8,1  Now  in  an  action  of  debt  (on  an  indenture)  brought  for  the  forty  pounds; 
whether  the  defendant  can  plead  payment  of  the  twenty  pounds  without  an  acquit- 
tance or  not  ?  And  it  seemed  to  Spelman  Fitzherbert  and  Shelley  that  he  cannot. 
Yet  quare,  for  there  are  many  precedents  to  the  contrary,"  Anon.  (1535)  Dyer  6a. 

VOL.  VIII.— 6 


&2      CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

laid  down  in  argument,  and  apparently  acceded  to  by  the  court.1 
One  mitigation  of  the  strictness  of  this  principle  was,  however, 
established  in  Blake 's  Case.  It  was  settled  that  if  the  cause  of 
action  was  not  solely  on  the  deed  to  recover  the  money  due  under 
it,  but  to  recover  unliquidated  damages  for  the  breach  of  some 
other  duty,  accord  and  satisfaction  was  a  good  discharge ;  "  for 
the  action  is  not  merely  grounded  on  the  deed,  but  also  on  the 
deed  and  the  wrong  subsequent."  2 

In  the  second  place,  if  a  simple  contract  was  still  executory  it 
could  be  discharged  by  the  simple  agreement  of  the  parties.  "  If 
I  promise  to  J.S.,"  said  Dodderidge,  J.,  in  1616,3  "that  if  he  build 
a  house  upon  my  land  before  Michaelmas,  I  will  pay  him  a  hundred 
pounds,  and  I  countermand  it  before  he  hath  done  anything  con- 
cerning the  house,  it  is  a  good  countermand  " ;  for,  as  was  said  in 
Langden  v.  Stokes,4"  a  promise  made  verbally  may  be  discharged 
by  words  before  breach,  or,  as  Coke  put  it  in  Peytoe's  Case,5  "as  a 
contract  upon  consideration  may  commence  by  word,  so  by  agree- 
ment by  word  for  any  valuable  consideration  it  may  be  dissolved." 

In  the  third  place,  although  the  doctrine  of  consideration  as 
thus  applied  to  the  discharge  of  contracts,  allowed  that  an  agree- 
ment to  discharge  an  executory  contract  was  good,  because  the 
promise  of  the  one  party  to  discharge  was  consideration  for  the 
promise  of  the  other ;  the  same  reasoning  made  it  necessary  to 
deny  the  validity  of  a  mere  agreement  to  discharge,  if  it  was  made 
by  a  person  who  had  fulfilled  his  duty  under  the  contract.  There 
could  be  no  consideration  for  such  an  agreement,  unless  the  party 
to  be  discharged  had  given  some  consideration  for  the  promise  to 
discharge  him.  In  the  days  when  a  wholly  executory  contract 
was  unknown,  it  is  clear  that  this  consideration  for  a  promise  to 
discharge  must  have  been  executed  ;  for,  as  we  have  seen,  neither 
debt,  nor,  in  its  earlier  days,  assumpsit,  lay,  unless  the  party  suing 
had  performed  his  part  of  the  agreement.  Therefore  the  rule  was 
laid  down  many  times  in  the  Middle  Ages,  and  repeated  in  the 
sixteenth  century,  that  it  was  only  an  accord  and  satisfaction  which 
would  discharge  a  contract,  or  any  other  obligation,  to  which  the 
party  making  the  accord  was  already  liable.6     The  rule  and  its 

1  "  In  a  writ  of  annuity  payment  is  plea  if  it  be  granted  out  of  the  land,  otherwise 
not.  And  although  the  truth  be  that  the  plaintiff  is  paid  his  money,  still  it  is  better  to 
suffer  a  mischief  to  one  man,  than  an  inconvenience  to  many,  which  would  subvert  a 
law;  for  if  matter  in  wiiting  may  be  so  easily  defeated  and  avoided  by  such  surmise 
and  naked  breath,  a  matter  in  writing  would  be  of  no  greater  authority  than  a  matter 
of  fact,"  Waberley  v.  Cockerel  (1542)  Dyer  at  ff.  51a,  51b. 

2  6  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  44a. 

3  Hurford  v.  Pile,  Cro.  Jac.  483  ;  cp.  Treswaller  v.  Keyne  (1622)  Cro.  Jac.  620. 

4  (1635)  Cro.  Car.  383.  6  (1612)  9  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  79b. 

6  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  90-91,  and  the  Y.BB.  there  cited  ;  Coke  summed  up  their  effect 
when  he  said  in  Peytoe's  Case,  (1612)  9  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  79b,  "  Every  accord  ought  to  be 
full  perfect  and  complete  :  for  if  divers  things  are  to  be  performed  by  the  accord,  the 
performance  of  part  is  not  sufficient,  but  all  ought  to  be  performed." 


DISCHARGE  83 

reasons  are  clearly  stated  in  the  following  passage  in  the  Doctor 
and  Student : * — "  Doctor.  And  if  a  man  promise  to  give  another 
xl  /*'  in  recompence  for  such  a  trespass  that  he  hath  done  him,  lyeth 
an  action  there?  Student.  I  suppose  nay,  and  the  cause  is  for 
that  such  promises  be  no  perfect  contracts ;  for  a  contract  is  pro- 
perly where  a  man  for  his  money  shall  have  by  assent  of  the  other 
partie  certain  goods  or  some  other  profit  at  the  time  of  the  contract 
or  after  :  but  if  the  thing  be  promised  for  a  cause  that  is  past  by 
way  of  recompence,  then  it  is  rather  an  accord  than  a  contract 
But  then  the  law  is  that  upon  such  accord  the  thing  that  is 
promised  in  recompence  must  be  paid,  or  delivered  in  hand,  for 
upon  an  accord  there  lyeth  no  action."  It  followed  that,  if  a  sum 
of  money  was  due  under  a  contract,  an  agreement  to  pay  a  lesser 
sum  followed  by  payment  would  be  no  accord  and  satisfaction, 
because  a  payment  of  a  lesser  sum,  when  a  larger  sum  was  due, 
was,  as  we  have  seen,2  no  consideration.  It  was  only  if  the  agree- 
ment was  to  do  something  else  in  satisfaction,  and  that  something 
was  performed,  that  there  was  an  accord  and  satisfaction  which 
would  discharge  the  contract ;  and  these  principles  are  still  part 
of  the  law.3 

So  long  as  only  those  contracts  were  actionable  which  were 
based  on  a  executed  consideration,  these  rules  were  a  logical 
application  of  the  doctrines  of  quid  pro  quo,  and  of  consideration 
as  then  accepted,  to  the  discharge  of  contracts.  But  we  have  seen 
that,  at  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century,  wholly  executory  con- 
tracts became  actionable  ;  and  that  in  that  case  the  promise  of  the 
one  party  was  accepted  as  being  the  consideration  for  the  counter- 
promise  by  the  other.4  Logically  this  extension  of  the  doctrine 
of  consideration  should  have  affected  the  law  as  to  accord  and 
satisfaction.  If  a  promise  for  a  promise  is  a  good  consideration 
for  making  a  contract,  a  promise  to  pay  or  do  anything  should  be 
a  sufficient  consideration  for  a  promise  to  discharge.3  This  view 
seems  to  have  been  taken  in  1602  in  the  case  of  Goring  v.  Goring  ;  6 
and  it  was  specifically  approved  in  1681  in  the  case  of  Case  v. 
Barber?  "Of  late,"  it  was  said  in  argument,  "it  hath  been  held 
that  upon  mutual  promises  an  action  lies,  and  consequently  there 
being  equal  remedy  on  both  sides  an  accord  may  be  pleaded  with- 
out execution  as  well  as  an  arbitrament,  and  by  the  same  reason 
that  an  arbitrament  is  a  good  plea« without  performance."8  "To 
which  the  court  agreed  ;  for  the  reason  of  the  law  being  changed, 

1  Bk.  II.  c.  24.  a  Above  20,  40. 

•Anson,  Contracts  (12th  ed.)  346.  «Vol.  iii  444-445. 

6  Street,  op.  tit.  ii  91-92.  «(i6o2)  Yelv.  11 ;  above  41. 

7T.  Raym.  450. 

8  For  arbitrament  see  above  81  n.  6 ;  the  reason  was  not  the  same,  see  Allen  v. 
Harris  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  122,  cited  below  84  n.  4. 


84       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

the  law  is  thereby  changed  ;  and  anciently  remedy  was  not  given 
for  mutual  promises,  which  is  now  given."  This  is  accepted  as 
good  law  by  Comyns  ; 1  but  how  far  it  represents  modern  law  is 
perhaps  a  little  uncertain. 

There  are  undoubtedly  a  large  number  of  cases  which  lay  it 
down  in  uncompromising  terms  that  it  is  only  an  accord  and  satis- 
faction which  will  discharge  a  contract.2  This  is  due  to  several 
causes.  To  a  large  extent  it  is  due,  as  Mr.  Street  has  pointed  out,3 
to  the  fact  that,  as  such  agreements  generally  embody  concessions 
to  debtors,  they  are  generally  made  with  a  view  to  performance, 
and  not  to  the  obtaining  of  a  counter-promise  from  the  debtor, 
which  may  very  likely  only  lead  to  fresh  litigation.  But  it  is  also 
due  to  two  other  causes  of  a  technical  kind.  In  the  first  place,  it 
is  due  to  the  weight  of  authority  which  came  from  a  time  before 
the  enforceability  of  wholly  executory  contracts  was  recognized. 
The  rule  that  an  accord  without  satisfaction  was  no  discharge  had 
hardened  into  a  fixed  rule  of  law  ;  its  basis  in  a  rudimentary  stage 
of  the  history  of  consideration  was  forgotten  ;  and  the  judges  there- 
fore failed  to  adapt  it  to  the  new  developments  of  that  doctrine.4 
In  the  second  place,  it  was  due  to  the  great  obscurity  which  long 
hung,  and  still  to  some  extent  hangs,  about  the  law  as  to  the  status 
of  promises  to  do  what  the  promisor  is  already  bound  to  do.5  But 
if  it  is  admitted  that  a  promise  by  A  to  B  to  perform  his  contractual 
duty  to  C  is  a  valid  consideration  for  a  counter-promise  by  B  to 
A,  it  is  difficult  to  see  why  a  promise  by  A,  who  is  liable  to  B, 
under  his  contract  with  him,  to  do  something  for  B,  should  not  be 
a  good  consideration  for  a  promise  by  B  to  discharge  A.  And, 
though  payment  of  a  lesser  sum  when  a  larger  sum  is  due  is 
certainly  not  a  discharge,6  it  may  well  be  that  a  promise  to  pay  a 
lesser  sum  may  be  a  valid  consideration  for  a  promise  of  discharge.7 

1  Digest,  Accord  B  4,  cited  above  22-23. 

2 Thus  Tindal,  C.J.,  laid  it  down  in  Bayley  v.  Homan  (1837)  3  Bing  N.C.  at  pp. 
920-921  that  'a  plea  of  accord  to  be  a  good  plea  must  show  an  accord  which  is  not 
executory  at  a  future  day,  but  which  ought  to  be  executed  and  has  been  executed  before 
action  brought  "  ;  after  citing  many  cases  to  this  effect,  he  said,  "  we  think  this  current 
of  authority  is  too  strong  to  be  met  by  the  doubts  expressed  by  the  court  in  Case  v. 
Barber" ;  see  also  the  cases  cited  1  S.L.C.  (roth  ed.)  336. 

3  Op.  cit.  ii  93. 

4  Thus  in  Allen  v.  Harris  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  122  the  court  said,  "  if  arbitra- 
ment be  pleaded  with  mutual  promises  to  perform  it,  though  the  party  has  not  performed 
his  part  who  brings  the  action,  yet  he  shall  maintain  his  action  ;  because  an  arbitrament 
is  like  a  judgment  and  the  party  may  have  his  remedy  upon  it.  But  upon  accord  no 
remedy  lies.  And  the  books  are  so  numerous,  that  an  accord  ought  to  be  executed, 
that  it  is  now  impossible  to  overthrow  all  the  books.  But  if  it  had  been  a  new  point  it 
might  be  worthy  of  consideration." 

6  Above  23-24,  41.  6  Above  40. 

7  As  it  is  said  in  1  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.)  336,  "  the  rational  distinction  seems  to  be,  that 
if  the  promise  be  received  in  satisfaction,  it  is  a  good  satisfaction  ;  but  if  the  perform- 
ance, not  the  promise,  is  intended  to  operate  in  satisfaction,  there  will  be  no  satisfaction 
without  performance,"  cp.  Edwards  v.  Hancher  (1875)  1  C.P.D.  in  where  the  pos- 
sibility of  a  promise,  if  received  in  satisfaction,  being  a  valid  discharge  seems  to  be 
admitted ;  and  see  the  other  cases  cited  1  S.L.C  336. 


DISCHARGE  85 

Whether  this  is  so  or  not  is  not  yet  settled.  But  there  is  a  little 
authority  in  favour  of  this  view  ; !  and  it  is  to  some  extent  supported, 
firstly,  by  some  of  the  not  very  satisfactory  reasons  given  for  uphold- 
ing the  validity  of  a  composition  with  creditors  ; 2  and,  secondly,  by 
the  rule  that  the  gift  of  a  negotiable  instrument  for  a  lesser  sum 
than  an  existing  debt  is  a  good  consideration  for  a  promise  to  dis- 
charge that  debt,3  for  a  negotiable  instrument  embodies  a  promise 
to  pay,  to  which  peculiar  incidents  are  annexed  by  the  law 
merchant4 

(iii)  The  novation.* 

The  name  novation  is  Roman ;  but  the  institution,  as  recog- 
nized by  the  common  law,  is,  as  Ames  has  said,  of  English  growth. 
The  Roman  novation  in  Justinian's  time  was  effected  through  the 
stipulation ;  but  the  common  law  never  recognized  a  contract  of 
this  kind  ;  and  therefore  the  English  novation  was  evolved  without 
reference  to  it,  when  the  development  of  the  English  contract 
system  had  reached  the  stage  at  which  this  evolution  was  possible. 

In  the  mediaeval  period  no  such  contract  was  possible.  This 
is  illustrated  by  a  case  of  the  year  1432,6  in  which  an  unsuccessful 
attempt  was  made  to  induce  the  court  to  admit  its  validity.  In 
that  case  Rolf  argued  in  effect  that,  if  B  is  indebted  to  C  for  £20, 
and  A  is  indebted  to  B  for  a  like  amount,  and  "  A  grants  to  C  to 
pay  C  the  £20  which  A  owes,  and  that  B  shall  be  discharged 
of  his  debt  to  C,  and  C  agrees  to  this,  and  B  also,  A  shall  now  be 
charged  to  C  for  this  debt  by  his  contract  and  own  act."  But 
Cotesmore,  J.,  and  the  whole  court  denied  this,  "for  although  all 
three  are  agreed  that  A  shall  pay  this  debt  for  B,  still  B  is  not 
discharged  of  his  debt  in  any  manner."  This  decision  was  inevit- 
able in  the  then  state  of  the  law.  As  Ames  has  pointed  out,  B 
could  be  discharged  of  his  liability  to  C  only  by  release  under  seal, 
or  by  accord  and  satisfaction  ;  while  A  could  be  made  liable  on 

1  Last  note. 

sSee  Good  v.  Cheesman  (1831)  2  B.  and  Ad.  at  p.  325,  where  Parke,  J.,  cites  the 
passage  from  Comyns's  Digest  Accord  B4  (above  22-23).  As  Ames  says,  Lectures 
on  Legal  History  334-335,  most  of  the  reasons  given  to  reconcile  this  decision  with  the 
rule  that  payment  of  part  of  a  debt  is  no  consideration  for  a  discharge  are  futile ; 
really  there  are  two  contracts  in  such  a  composition  :  (1)  between  the  debtor  and  his 
creditors,  the  debtor  promising  to  hand  over  certain  property,  and  the  creditors  pro- 
mising to  release  him  when  the  property  is  handed  over  to  a  trustee  for  them  ;  and  (2) 
between  the  creditors,  each  promising  only  to  exact  a  quota  of  his  debt  in  consideration 
of  the  others  promising  to  do  the  like ;  it  seems  to  me  that  the  only  way  in  which  the 
validity  of  the  first  of  these  contracts  can  be  upheld  is  by  saying  that  the  debtor's  new 
promise  is  something  different  from  his  existing  obligation  to  each  creditor. 

3  Goddard  v.  O'Brien  (1882)  9  Q.B.D.  37. 

*  For  the  history  of  negotiable  instruments  see  below  113  seqq. 

5  See  generally  Ames,  Lectures  on  Legal  History  298  seqq  ;  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  122 
seqq. 

8  Y.B.  11  Hy.  VI.  Pasch.  pi.  30  (p.  38) ;  Ames,  op.  cit.  298-299 ;  I  have  cited  the 
translation  given  by  Ames. 


86       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

his  contract  to  pay  C  only  by  action  of  debt ;  and  to  an  action  of 
debt  at  the  suit  of  C  he  could  not  be  liable,  because  he  had  received 
no  quid  pro  quo  from  C.  "  The  two  essential  features  of  a  novation 
— namely  the  extinguishment  of  the  original  obligation,  and  the 
creation  of  a  new  one  in  its  place — were  therefore  both  wanting  in 
the  case  supposed.  In  other  words,  novation  by  simple  agreement 
of  the  parties  was  at  that  time  a  legal  impossibility."  * 

When,  however,  it  was  recognized  at  the  close  of  the  sixteenth 
century,  that  an  executory  contract  based  on  the  mutual  promises 
of  the  two  parties  was  enforceable  by  assumpsit,  the  legal  im- 
possibility began  to  disappear.  In  161 1,  in  the  case  of  Flewellin 
v.  Rowe?  A  owed  money  to  C,  and  B  owed  money  to  A.  It  was 
agreed  by  all  three  that  B,  to  discharge  his  debt  to  A,  should 
hand  over  certain  goods  of  his  own  to  C,  and  that  C  should  take 
them  in  discharge  of  A's  debt  to  C.  B  did  not  hand  over  the  goods, 
but  converted  them  to  his  own  use.  C  thereupon  brought  trover 
against  B  ;  and  it  was  held  that  he  was  entitled  to  recover.  The 
court  treated  it  as,  in  effect,  similar  to  the  case  where  one  has 
promised  to  bail  goods  to  another  to  the  use  of  a  third.  Just  as 
the  third  person  had  a  right  of  action  in  such  a  case  to  redress  the 
wrong  done  to  him,  so  here,  C  had  suffered  a  similar  wrong  for 
which  he  ought  to  have  his  action.3  This  case,  therefore,  shows 
that  by  the  somewhat  roundabout  method  of  an  action  of  conver- 
sion effect  could  be  given  to  a  novation. 

The  case  of  Roe  v.  Haugh  (1697)4  marks  a  later  stage  in  the 
history  of  the  novation,  and  indicates  the  beginning  of  modern  theory 
upon  which  such  an  arrangement  rests.  In  that  case  B  owed  A 
£42.  C,  in  consideration  that  A  would  accept  him  as  his  debtor 
for  the  £<\2  due  from  B,  undertook  to  pay  the  ^42  to  A.  C, 
having  failed  to  pay,  an  action  was  brought  against  him  ;  but,  as 
the  declaration  had  not  alleged  that  A  had  promised  to  discharge 
B,  no  consideration  for  C's  promise  was  apparent.  On  this  ground 
three  judges — Blencowe  and  Powell,  JJ.,  and  Ward,  C.B. — thought 
that  C  was  entitled  to  judgment ;  but  four — Powys  and  Lechmere, 
BB.,  Nevil,  J.  and  Treby,  C.J. — held  that,  as  a  verdict  had  been 
found  for  the  plaintiff,  "  they  should  do  what  they  could  to  help  it ; 

1  Ames,  op.  cit.  299.  2  1  Bulstr.  68. 

3  "  Notwithstanding  the  third  person  here  to  whom  the  goods  ought  to  have  been 
bailed  had  never  the  possession  of  them,  yet  this  conversion  and  nonfeasance  of  that 
which  he  ought  to  have  done,  is  a  wrong  and  very  prejudicial  to  C  the  third  person.  And 
for  this  wrong  and  prejudice  he  may  have  his  action  upon  the  case.  .  .  .  The  whole 
court  also  clearly  agreed  in  this — that  this  not  bailing  over,  and  delivery  of  the  goods 
by  B  the  first  bailee  unto  C  in  satisfaction  of  the  debt  to  A,  and  according  to  the 
agreement  made  between  A  and  B,  that  this  doth  clearly  amount  in  law  to  make  a 
conversion.  And  that  by  this,  he  hath  made  himself  subject  and  liable  to  an  action  to 
be  brought  by  the  party  to  whom  he  should  have  delivered  the  goods,"  ibid. 

4  12  Mod.  133  ;  S.C.  1  Salk.  29. 


DISCHARGE  87 

to  which  end  they  would  not  consider  it  only  as  a  promise  on  the 
part  of  C,  for  as  such  it  would  not  bind  him,  except  B  was  dis- 
charged ;  but  they  would  construe  it  to  be  a  mutual  promise,  viz., 
that  C  promised  to  A  to  pay  the  debt  of  B,  and  A  on  the  other 
side  promised  to  discharge  B,  so  that  though  B  be  not  actually 
discharged,  yet  if  A  sues  him,  he  subjects  himself  to  an  action  for 
the  breach  of  the  promise."  l 

The  last  sentence  in  this  judgment  shows  that  one  step  was  still 
wanting  to  complete  the  efficacy  of  a  novation.  The  contract 
between  A  and  C  could  not  be  directly  enforced  by  B,  because  he 
was  a  stranger  to  it  Therefore  A,  if  he  was  prepared  to  expose 
himself  to  an  action  by  C  for  the  breach  of  his  promise,  could  still 
sue  B.2  The  last  stage  was  reached  when  it  was  recognized  that 
the  agreement  between  A  and  C  operated  to  extinguish  B's  debt, 
so  that  A  could  no  longer  sue  B.  This  was  recognized  in  1789 
by  Buller,  J.,  who  said,  "suppose  A  owes  B  £100,  and  B  owes  C 
.£100,  and  it  is  agreed  between  them  that  A  shall  pay  C  the  £100; 
B's  debt  is  extinguished,  and  C  may  recover  the  sum  against  A."  3 
In  other  words,  B,  though  he  cannot  sue  on  a  contract  made 
between  A  and  C,  can  take  advantage  of  the  extinguishment  of 
his  obligation  to  C,  which  results  from  the  contract  between  A 
and  G*  The  various  applications  of  this  principle  in  the  law  of 
partnership  and  otherwise  belong  to  a  later  period  in  the  history 
of  the  law.5 

The  manner  in  which  the  law  upon  these  three  topics — the 
invalidity,  the  enforcement,  and  the  breach  of  contract — was  being 
shaped  during  this  period,  illustrate  the  manner  in  which  the 
English  law  of  contract,  as  developed  in  and  through  the  action 
of  assumpsit,  was  being  co-ordinated  with  other  branches  of  the 
common  law.  It  was  being  adapted  to  the  established  rules  which 
regulated  the  status  of  such  persons  as  married  women  and  infants  ; 
and,  just  as  in  the  growth  of  the  doctrine  of  consideration,  we  can 
trace  the  influence  of  older  ideas  which  had  originated  in  the  action 
of  debt,  so  in  many  of  these  branches  of  the  law  we  can  trace  the 
influence  of  older  ideas  originating  in  doctrines,  first  applied  to 
contracts  under  seal  and  more  especially  to  bonds,  and  developed 
mainly  in  connection  with  the  land  law.  But,  as  I  have  already 
pointed  out,  and  as  we  can  see  from  the  history  just  related,  the 
main  lines  of  development  were  shaped  by  the  conditions  under 
which  the  various  branches  of  the  action  of  assumpsit  lay.  At 
the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  these  developments  were  in 

1  12  Mod.  at  p.  134.  2  Ames,  op.  cit.  300. 

3  Tatlock  v.  Harris  3  T.R.  at  p.  180.  *  Lytt  v.  Ault  (1852)  7  Exch.  66g, 

'Ames,  op.  cit.  300-509;  Pollock,  Contracts  (gth  ed.)  218-219, 


88       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

many  cases  as  yet  rudimentary.  But,  at  that  period,  we  can  see 
the  beginnings  of  another  influence  which,  in  the  following  period, 
will  exercise  a  very  powerful  effect  on  the  further  developments  of 
this  branch  of  the  law — the  influence  of  mercantile  custom.  We 
shall  see  that  the  theory  of  contract,  as  developed  in  and  through 
the  action  of  assumpsit,  was  sufficient  to  enable  the  common  law 
to  keep  and  develop  that  jurisdiction  over  commercial  law  which 
it  had  acquired  at  the  close  of  this  period.1  But  before  I  deal 
with  the  beginnings  of  a  body  of  law,  which  was  destined  to  have 
so  great  an  influence  on  the  future  development,  not  only  of  the 
law  of  contract,  but  also  of  many  other  branches  of  English  law, 
I  must  say  something  of  the  latest  development  of  the  action  of 
assumpsit,  which  resulted  in  the  creation  of  our  modern  law  of 
quasi-contract. 

§  3.  Quasi-contract 

We  have  seen  that,  during  the  mediaeval  period,  the  actions  of 
debt  and  account  enabled  the  law  to  recognize  and  to  give  effect 
to  rights  arising  from  certain  relations,  which,  at  the  present  day, 
we  should  style  quasi-contractual.  Thus  debt  could  be  used  to 
recover  statutory  penalties,  forfeitures  under  bye-laws,  amercements, 
and  money  ordered  to  be  paid  by  the  judgment  of  a  court ;  and 
either  debt  or  account  lay  at  the  suit  of  a  beneficiary  to  whose  use 
money  had  been  paid.2  Similarly,  account  lay  when  A  handed 
over  money  to  B  to  employ  for  his  (A's)  use,  or  when  A's  factor 
or  bailiff  had  received  money  to  his  (A's)  use ;  and,  at  the  end  of 
the  sixteenth  century,  it  was  held  that  if  A,  by  reason  of  a  mistake 
or  in  consequence  of  false  or  fraudulent  representations  made  by 
B,  had  paid  money  to  B,  he  could  bring  account  against  B.3  We 
have  seen,  too,  that  in  the  sixteenth  century  the  spheres  of  debt 
and  account  had  come  to  be  almost  concurrent ;  and  that  there- 
fore, when  indebitatus  assumpsit  had  become  almost  concurrent  with 
debt,  it  followed  that  indebitatus  assumpsit  came  to  be  almost 
concurrent  with  account.4 

These  developments,  therefore,  opened  the  possibility  of 
extending  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  remedy  many  of  those  causes 
of  action  which  were  remediable,  either  by  the  actions  of  debt  or 
account.  It  was  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century  that 
this  extension  was  made,  and  that  it  was  used,  firstly,  to  enforce 
certain  of  those  statutory  or  customary  duties  which  were  enforce- 
able by  action  of  debt ;  and,  secondly,  to  remedy  cases  of  unjust 

1  Vol.  i  558,  568-573  ;  vol.  v  140-148. 

2  Vol.  iii  420,  425-428 ;  cp.  vol.  ii  366-369. 

3  Vol.  iii  427.  4  Ibid  428. 


QUASI-CONTRACT  89 

enrichment  which  were  remediable  by  the  actions  of  debt  or 
account.  The  latter  was  the  most  fruitful  line  of  development, 
and  by  its  means  the  largest  part  of  our  present  law  of  quasi- 
contract  was  constructed. 

It  would  not  however  be  true  to  say  that  the  whole  of  our 
modern  law  of  quasi-contract  has  grown  up  round  this  latest 
extension  of  indebitatus  assumpsit.  This  action  could  never  be 
brought  for  money  due  under  a  judgment;1  and  certain  duties 
imposed  by  law  on  carriers,  innkeepers,  and  others  were  still  en- 
forceable, as  they  had  been  enforceable  in  the  Middle  Ages,2  by 
an  action  on  the  case."  These  cases,  and  other  similar  causes  of 
action  which  have  arisen  later,4  are  on  the  border  line  between 
contract  and  tort,  and  should  perhaps  be  classed  as  quasi-torts,  if 
the  common  law  had  ever  recognized  such  a  category  of  obliga- 
tions. But  it  never  recognized  such  a  category,  because  such 
breaches  of  duty  could  be  sued  on  by  a  form  of  assumpsit ;  and, 
though  this  form  of  assumpsit  was,  as  we  have  seen,  really 
delictual  in  character,5  the  fact  that  it  was  a  form  of  assumpsit  led 
the  lawyers  to  class  these  obligations  as  quasi-contracts.  Parts 
therefore  of  our  modern  law  of  quasi-contract  are  based  on  the 
competence  of  the  old  action  of  debt,  and  parts  on  innominate 
actions  on  the  case. 

In  this  section  I  propose  to  say  something  of  the  growth  of 
that  part  of  the  law  of  quasi-contract  which  is  derived  from  the 
extension  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  this  new  sphere  of  liability. 
I  shall  divide  the  subject  according  to  the  two  main  lines  on  which 
this  extension  proceeded :  firstly,  its  extension  to  enforce  certain 
legal  duties  formerly  enforceable  by  action  of  debt ;  and,  secondly, 
its  extension  to  remedy  cases  of  unjust  enrichment.  Lastly,  I 
shall  indicate  the  manner  in  which,  by  reason  of  these  develop- 
ments, the  growth  of  the  modern  law  was  made  possible. 

(i)  The  extension  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  enforce  certain 
legal  duties  formerly  enforceable  by  action  of  debt. 

We  have  seen  that  in  Slade's  Case 6  it  was  recognized  that, 
from  the  existence  of  a  debt,  the  law  would  imply  a  promise  to 
pay  it,  which  promise  could  be  enforced  by  indebitatus  assumpsit ; 7 
and  that  this  decision  naturally  led  to  the  recognition  of  contractual 
duties  implied  from  the  acts  of  the  parties.8     Ihe  extension  of  the 

1  Ames,  Lectures  on  Legal  History  i6o;  cp.  Bl.  Comm.  iii  158-159. 
1  Vol.  iii  385-386,  448. 

3  Ames,  op.  cit.  161,  and  cases  there  cited  ;  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  236-237. 

4  See  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  237-238 ;  as  he  points  out  the  agent's  implied  warranty  of 
authority  recognized  in  Collen  v.  Wright  (1857)  8  E-  and  B.  647  is  a  late  illustration 
of  this  principle. 

8  Vol.  iii  448-450.  « (1602)  4  Co.  Rep.  92b. 

7  Vol.  iii  443-444.  8  Ibid  446-447. 


90       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

idea  of  contractual  duty  implied  from  the  acts  of  the  parties, 
tended  to  promote  the  recognition  of  duties  which  diverged  more 
and  more  widely  from  the  sphere  of  true  contract.  Thus,  we  have 
seen  that  it  had  come  to  be  recognized  that  an  infant  could  be 
made  liable  to  pay  a  reasonable  price  for  necessaries  supplied  to 
him  by  action  of  assumpsit  on  a  quantum  meruit ; 1  and  this 
liability  could  be  enforced,  though  the  infant  was  too  young  to  be 
capable  of  consent.2  But  as  soon  as  the  idea  of  consent  which 
underlies  assumpsit  begins  to  be  whittled  away,  it  is  obvious  that 
there  will  be  a  tendency,  on  account  of  its  procedural  advantages, 
to  use  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  enforce,  not  only  those  debts  which 
arise  from  a  contract  express  or  implied,  but  also  those  debts  which 
are  imposed  by  law. 

At  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  the  attempt  to  use 
indebitatus  assumpsit  in  this  way  was  made ;  and  it  was  at  first 
permitted  by  the  courts  almost  without  opposition.  Thus  in  1676, 
in  the  case  of  The  Mayor  of  London  v.  Gorry,3  assumpsit  was 
brought  for  money  due  by  custom  for  scavage.  "The  jury  found 
the  duty  to  be  due,  but  that  no  promise  was  expressly  made  : 
and  whether  assumpsit  lies  for  this  money  thus  due  by  custom 
without  express  promise  was  the  question  :  resolved  it  does."  In 
1679  this  case  was  followed,  and  the  company  of  Barber  Surgeons 
of  London  was  allowed  to  recover,  by  this  form  of  action,  a  penalty 
imposed  on  a  member  for  breach  of  a  bye-law.4  In  168 1  it  was 
held  in  the  Exchequer  Chamber  that  a  customary  payment  known 
as  weighage  could  be  recovered  in  this  way  ; 5  in  1689  6  the  gentle- 
man ushers  were  allowed  to  recover  the  customary  fee  due  from  a 
person  who  had  been  knighted  ;  and  in  the  same  year  the  executrix 
of  a  lord  of  the  manor  was  allowed  to  recover  a  fine  set  upon  a 
copyholder  by  her  testator.7 

But  in  the  last  cited  case  Holt,  C.J.,  dissented.  He  refused 
to  follow  the  prevailing  opinion,  and  to  allow  that,  because  debt 
lay,    indebitatus  assumpsit  must    therefore  necessarily    lie.8     He 

1  Above  52. 

2  As  Mr.  Street  points  out,  op.  cit.  ii  204,  "  insane  and  drunken  persons  are  upon 
the  same  footing  as  infants  in  respect  to  their  liability  to  compensate  for  necessaries. 
The  law  makes  the  contract  for  them,  or  at  least  imposes  the  legal  duty  on  the 
particular  facts  of  the  case  "  ;  as  he  points  out,  loc.  cit.,  the  husband's  liability  to  be 
sued  by  assumpsit  for  necessaries  supplied  to  his  wife,  whom  he  has  wrongfully 
deserted,  rests  on  the  same  basis;  as  we  have  seen,  vol.  iii  530,  it  was  in  Manby  v. 
Scott  (1663)  1  Sid.  109  that  it  was  first  recognized  that  this  liability  could  be  enforced 
in  this  way. 

3  2  Lev.  174.  4  The  Barber  Surgeons  of  London  v.  Pelson  2  Lev.  252. 

5  Mayor  of  London  v.  Hunt  3  Lev.  37. 

6  Duppa  v.  Gerrard  1  Shower  K.B.  78. 

7  Shuttleworth  v.  Garnet  3  Lev.  261 ;  S.  C.  Comb.  151. 

8  "  It  doth  not  follow  that  an  indebitatus  assumpsit  lies  because  debt  lies ;  where 
wager  of  law  doth  not  lie,  there  an  indebitatus  assumpsit  don't  lie,  and  it  is  mischievous 
to  extend  it  further  than  Slade's  Case,"  Comb.  151. 


QUASI  CONTRACT  91 

objected  to  this  extension  on  two  grounds.  In  the  first  place,  he 
saw  that  in  principle  there  was  a  logical  chasm  between  such 
cases  as  Slade's  Case,  where  there  was  a  duty  imposed  by  the 
implied  consent  of  the  parties,  and  cases  where  the  duty  was 
imposed  by  law  without  the  consent  of  the  parties.  This  distinc- 
tion was  pointed  out  in  Shower's  argument  in  the  case  of  the  City  of 
York  v.  Toun}  It  was  assented  to  by  Holt,  who,  in  another  case, 
said  that  "the  notion  of  promises  in  law  was  a  metaphysical 
notion,  for  the  law  makes  no  promise,  but  where  there  is  a  promise 
of  the  party."  2  In  the  second  place,  he  saw  that  to  permit  these 
penalties  to  be  recovered  by  this  form  of  action  meant,  firstly, 
allowing  the  plaintiff  to  state  his  case  generally,  so  that  the  defen- 
dant was  embarrassed  in  making  his  defence ; 3  and,  secondly, 
leaving  the  whole  question  of  liability  to  a  jury,  without  giving 
the  court  power  to  pronounce  on  the  reasonableness  of  the  custom 
or  bye-law.-4  When  Holt  had  made  up  his  mind  he  was  apt  to 
express  his  opinion  with  vehemence.  In  the  City  of  York  v.  Toun, 
on  a  motion  being  made  that  the  action  might  stay  till  the  next 
term,  he  said  "that  it  should  stay  till  Doomsday  with  all  his 
heart "  ; 5  and  in  another  case  he  said,  "  away  with  your  Indebitatus, 
'tis  but  as  a  bargain  and  no  Indebitatus  lyeth."  6  He  tried  also  to 
win  over  the  other  judges  to  his  opinion.  Raymond  notes 7  that, 
a  few  days  after  the  hearing  of  the  City  of  York  v.  Toun,  "  I  met 
the  Lord  Chief  Justice  Treby  visiting  the  Lord  Chief  Justice  Holt 
at  his  house.  And  Holt  repeated  the  said  case  to  him,  as  a  new 
attempt  to  extend  the  indebitatus  assumpsit,  which  had  been  too 
much  encouraged  already.  And  Treby,  Chief  Justice,  seemed 
also  to  be  of  the  same  opinion  with  Holt" 

Holt  did  not  succeed  in  bringing  the  other  judges  round  to  his 
opinion,  or  in  stopping  this  development  of  the  sphere  of  indebi- 
tatus assumpsit  In  the  case  of  Shuttleworth  v.  Garnet 8  he  was  in 
a  minority  of  one;  in  the  City  of  York  v.  Toun9  Rokeby,  J., 
dissented  from  his  opinion ;  and  Holt's  successors  allowed  in- 
debitatus assumpsit  to  be  brought  in  these10  and  similar  cases.11 
In  fact,  they  saw  that  the  scope  of  the  action  had  been  so  extended 

1 "  How  can  there  be  any  privity  or  assent  implied  when  a  fine  is  imposed  on  a 
man  against  his  will,"  (1700)  5  Mod.  444. 

2  Starke  v.  Cheeseman  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  538. 

3  "  An  indebitatus  assumpsit  is  laid  generally,  and  the  defendant  can't  tell  how  to 
make  his  defence,  but  debt  is  laid  more  particularly,"  Comb.  151. 

*  "  It  is  hard  that  customs,  bye-laws,  rights  to  impose  fines,  charters,  and  every- 
thing should  be  left  to  a  jury,"  City  of  York  v.  Toun  (1700)  5  Mod.  444. 

5  1  Ld.  Raym.  502.  •  Anon.  (1695)  Holt.  35.  7 1  Ld.  Raym.  502. 

8  3  Lev.  261.  »  1  Ld.  Raym.  502. 

10  See  e.g.  Mayor  of  Exeter  v.  Trimlet  (1759)  2  Wils.  95  ;  Seward  v.  Baker  (1787) 
1  T.R.  616. 

11  Thus  it  was  held  in  Dupleix  v.  De  Roven  (1705)  2  Vern.  540  that  indebitatus 
assumpsit  lay  on  a  foreign  judgment 


92       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

in  the  seventeenth  century,  that  this  further  extension,  though 
illogical  if  regarded  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  original  theory 
on  which  the  action  was  based,  was  inevitable.  Even  if  Holt's 
views  had  prevailed,  and  the  right  to  bring  indebitatus  assumpsit 
in  these  cases  had  been  denied,  many  cases  would  have  been  left, 
in  which  the  supposed  agreement  upon  which  it  was  brought  was 
equally  fictitious.  That  this  was  so  we  shall  see  if  we  look  at  the 
manner  in  which  this  form  of  action  had  been  applied  to  remedy 
cases  where  one  man  had  enriched  himself  unjustly  at  the  expense 
of  another. 

(2)   The  extension  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  remedy  cases  of 
unjust  enrichment. 

Ames  has  very  truly  said  that  "the  most  fruitful  manifestations 
of  the  doctrine  that  one  person  shall  not  unjustly  enrich  himself  at 
the  expense  of  another,  are,  in  early  law,  to  be  found  in  the  action 
of  account."  x  It  is  because  account  and  debt  had  become  largely 
coterminous,  that  it  was  possible  to  extend  indebitatus  assumpsit  to 
this  new  sphere,  lhat  this  was  so  we  shall  see  if  we  look  at  two 
sixteenth-century  cases,  which  turned  on  the  sphere  of  assumpsit, 
and  compare  them  with  the  very  different  notions  as  to  its  sphere 
which  were  growing  up  in  the  seventeenth  century. 

In  1 573,  in  Tottenham  and  Beding fields  Case?  it  was  held 
that,  where  a  defendant  had  carried  off  and  sold  certain  tithe  pro- 
duce belonging  to  the  plaintiff  as  parson,  account  did  not  lie.  The 
defendant,  it  was  pointed  out,  was  merely  a  wrongdoer.  There 
was  no  privity  between  him  and  the  plaintiff,  as  in  the  case  where 
one  had  received  another's  money  as  bailiff  or  agent  for  him.  He 
had  assumed  to  take  property  as  owner,  and  in  such  a  case  account 
was  not  a  proper  remedy.3  In  1595,  in  the  case  of  H owlet  v. 
Osbournf  it  was  held  that  assumpsit  did  not  lie  where  A  de- 
livered £\o  to  the  defendant  to  deliver  to  the  plaintiff,  and  the 
defendant,  after  promising  the  plaintiff  to  pay  it  to  him,  failed  to 
do  so.  But  it  is  clear  that  both  these  were  cases  in  which  one 
man  had  been  enriched  at  the  expense  of  another ;  and,  as  we 
shall  now  see,  the  extensions  made  in  the  scope  of  indebitatus 
assumpsit  during  the  seventeenth  century,  provided  a  remedy  both 
for  them  and  for  other  analogous  cases. 

We  can  distinguish  three  main  classes  of  cases : — (i)  actions 
to  recover  money  upon  a  total  failure  of  consideration  ;  (ii)  actions 

1  Lectures  on  Legal  History,  163.  2  3  Leo.  24. 

3  "  The  action  doth  not  lie,  for  here  is  not  any  privity  ;  for  wrongs  are  always 
done  without  privity.  ...  As  soon  as  the  tithes  were  severed  by  the  parishioners, 
there  they  were  presently  in  the  plaintiff,  and  therefore  the  defendant  by  taking  of  them 
was  a  wrongdoer,  and  no  action  of  accompt  lieth  against  him,"  ibid  per  Manwood,  J. 

4  Cro.  Eliza  380. 


QUASI-CONTRACT  93 

to  recover  money  paid  to  a  person  to  whom  it  was  not  due  ;  and 
(iii)  actions  to  recover  money  from  a  person  who  had  wrongfully 
taken  it 

(i)  By  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century,  it  was  well 
established  that  the  action  would  lie  to  recover  back  money  paid 
under  a  contract,  where  the  consideration  had  wholly  failed.  In 
Briggs  Case1  (1624)  A  promised  to  make  a  lease  to  B,  and  B 
paid  A  a  large  fine  for  the  lease.  Before  the  lease  was  made  A 
was  evicted  from  the  land.  It  was  held  that  B  could  sue  by 
action  on  the  case  to  recover  damages  for  the  loss  of  his  bargain ; 
and  it  should  be  noted  that  the  court  declined  to  prohibit  the 
Council  of  Wales  from  hearing  the  case,  because  "  ceo  case  est  mixt 
ove  equity."  Holt  was  willing  to  follow  this  case,  and  to  rule 
that  in  such  cases  of  total  failure  of  consideration  an  action  on  the 
case  could  be  brought ;  but  he  at  first  refused  to  allow  that  in- 
debitatus assumpsit  lay.  He  considered  that  the  cause  of  action 
was  in  tort,  and  therefore  remediable  by  an  action  in  tort,  and  not 
by  a  form  of  action  which  seemed  to  imply  that  the  liability  was 
somehow  contractual.2  Thus  in  1696,  in  the  case  of  Dewbery  v. 
Chapman?  the  defendant,  representing  falsely  that  he  was  a  free- 
man of  London,  took  the  plaintiffs  son  as  apprentice,  and  promised 
to  make  him  a  freeman  of  London.  In  consideration  thereof  the 
plaintiff  paid  him  £30.  The  defendant  could  not  fulfil  this 
promise  as  he  was  not  himself  a  freeman.  Holt  ruled  that  the 
plaintiff  could  not  recover  his  £30  by  indebitatus  assumpsit,  but 
that  he  must  bring  an  action  on  the  case  ; 4  and  in  1 698  he  gave 
a  similar  ruling.5  But  a  little  later,  in  the  case  of  Holmes  v.  Hall 
(1705),5  he  altered  his  opinion,  though  it  would  seem  somewhat 
unwillingly.6  He  there  held  that,  where  an  executor  had  paid  X 
a  sum  of  money  for  the  delivery  up  of  certain  writings  belonging 
to  his  testator,  and  X  then  refused  to  deliver  them  up,  the  executor 
could  recover  the  money  so  paid  by  indebitatus  assumpsit. 
"  Many  such  actions,"  he  said,  "have  been  maintained  for  earnests 
in   bargains    when   the   bargainer    would   not    perform,    and  for 

1  Palmer  364. 
_  s  **  Where  upon  a  reckoning,  a  man  receives  more  money  from  me  than  he  ought, 
an  indebitatus  will  lie  ;  nay,  it  hath  prevailed  further,  where  money  was  paid  for  lees 
which  were  not  justly  due  (though  it  is  hard  to  maintain  that),  but  where  there  is  a 
bargain,  tho'  a  corrupt  one,  or  where  one  sells  goods  that  were  not  his  own,  I  will 
never  allow  an  indebitatus,"  Anon.  (1698)  Comb.  447. 

3  Holt  35. 

4  "  The  defendant  hath  cheated  the  plaintiff  of  his  money,  and  the  plaintiff  hath 
no  remedy,  unless  by  special  action  of  the  case  for  not  making  him  a  freeman,"  ibid. 

5  Comb.  447,  cited  above  n.  2.  5  6  Mod.  161. 

6  '•  These  cases  of  indebitatus  for  money  received  to  use  have  been  carried  too  far, 
and  nobody  would  more  willingly  check  them  than  I  would,"  ibid  ;  in  the  report  of 
this  case  in  Holt  at  p.  36,  counsel  cited  a  similar  case,  where  Holt  had  non-suited  the 
plaintiff — "  which  Holt  utterly  denied." 


94       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

premiums  for  insurance  when  the  ship  etc.  did  not  go  the 
voyage."  1 

(ii)  In  the  course  of  the  seventeenth  century  indebitatus 
assumpsit  was  allowed  to  be  brought  by  A,  when  he  had  paid 
money  to  B  which  was  not  in  fact  due,  under  such  circumstances 
that  B  had  no  right  to  retain  it.  In  the  earlier  part  of  the 
century  it  was  thought  that  in  this  case,  as  in  the  case  of  failure 
of  consideration,  the  proper  remedy  was  action  on  the  case.  Thus 
it  was  held  in  the  case  of  Cavendish  v.  Middleton  (1629) 2  that, 
where  a  vendor  of  goods,  who  had  already  been  paid,  exacted 
payment  a  second  time,  case  lay  to  get  back  the  amount  thus 
wrongfully  exacted.  But  it  was  held  in  1657  that  indebitatus 
assumpsit  lay  to  get  back  money  paid  to  X,  who  was  afterwards 
proved  to  have  had  no  right  to  receive  it ; 3  and  in  the  latter  part 
of  the  century  the  principle  became  established,  and  was  applied  to 
a  large  number  of  different  cases.  Thus  it  was  said  in  1692  that, 
if  money  was  paid  to  a  stakeholder  to  abide  the  result  of  a  wager, 
the  winner  could  recover  it  from  him  by  this  action,  as  it  was  money 
received  by  the  stakeholder  to  his  use.4  Similarly,  money  could 
be  recovered  back  which  had  been  paid  under  a  judgment  which 
was  void,  because  the  court  had  no  jurisdiction  ; 5  or  money  paid  by 
mistake,  fraud,  or  extorted  by  duress.6  But  money  paid  under  a 
contract  void  for  illegality  could  not  be  recovered  back  if  the 
plaintiff  was  particeps  criminis.7  It  would  seem  that  Holt  was 
averse  to  some  of  these  extensions  of  the  action ; 8  but  it  is  clear 
from  the  cases  decided  in  his  time  and  later  that  his  opposition  did 
not  stop  the  development  of  this  principle. 

(iii)  As  early  as  1573  Harper,  J.,  had,  in  his  dissenting 
judgment  in    Tottenham  and  Bedingfield's  Case,9  expressed  the 

1  Holt  at  p.  36.  2  Cro.  Car.  141. 

3Bonnel  v.  Foulke  2  Sid.  4 — "  Si  jeo  pay  monies  in  satisfaction  del  duty  et  come 
duty,  et  il  a  qui  est  pay  nad  title  de  ceo  receiver,  et  issint  le  duty  n'est  satisfie,  il  a  qui 
est  pay  est  in  debt  a  moy,  et  issint  jeo  maintainer  action  vers  luy." 

*  Case  cited  by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  Martin  v.  Sitwell  1  Shower,  K.B.,  at  p.  157  as 
adjudged  by  Wyndham,  J. 

6  Newdigate  v.  Davy  (1694)  1  Ld.  Raym.  742 — the  money  had  been  paid  under 
a  sentence  of  James  II. 's  illegal  court  of  High  Commission. 

6Tomkyns  v.  Barnet  (1694)  Skin,  412  per  Holt,  C.J. ;  "The  cases  of  payments 
by  mistake  or  deceit  are  not  to  be  disputed  "  per  curiam  Astley  v.  Reynolds  (1732) 
2  Stra.  at  p.  916;  it  was  held  in  that  case  that  the  action  lay  for  money  extorted  by 
duress  of  goods. 

7  Tomkins  v.  Bernet  (1693)  *  Salk.  22 ;  some  of  the  reported  reasons  for  this 
decision  were  disapproved  by  Lord  Mansfield  in  Smith  v.  Bromley  (1760)  2  Dougl. 
697  n.,  though  he  did  not  dissent  from  the  general  principle;  cp.  Clarke  v.  Shee 
(1774)  1  Cowp.  at  pp.  199,  200;  in  fact  the  general  principle  is  stated  quite  clearly  by 
Holt  in  the  report  of  Tomkyns  v.  Barnet  in  Skin.  412;  the  case  of  Wilkinson  v. 
Kitchin  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  89,  in  which  Holt  is  reported  as  having  laid  down  the 
contrary  rule,  is  obviously  wrong. 

8 Comb.  447,  cited  above  93  n.  2  ;  cp.  Skin.  412. 
9  3  Leo.  24  ;  above  92. 


QUASI-CONTRACT  95 

opinion  that  a  wrongdoer  might  be  made  liable  in  account,  by 
charging  him  with  taking  the  property  as  the  rightful  owner's 
agent.1  This  view  prevailed  in  the  latter  half  of  the  seventeenth 
century ;  and  it  was  held  that  indebitatus  assumpsit  could  be 
brought  by  A  against  B,  where  B  had  taken  or  acquired  money  or 
other  property  which  in  fact  belonged  to  A.  Thus  in  1676,  in  the 
case  of  Woodward  v.  Aston?  indebitatus  assumpsit  was  brought  by 
the  joint  holder  of  an  office  against  his  fellow  who  had  taken  all 
the  profits,  and  no  one  objected  to  the  form  of  the  action ;  and 
when,  in  the  following  year,  this  objection  was  made  in  a  case  of  a 
similar  kind,  the  objection  was  over-ruled.3  In  1678,  in  the  case 
of  Howard  v.  Wood,  the  court,  though  it  doubted  the  correctness 
of  these  decisions,  declined  to  over-rule  them,  as  it  considered  that 
the  law  was  too  well  settled4  Holt,  at  first  reluctantly,  acquiesced 
in  them.5  But  in  1706,  in  the  case  of  Lamine  v.  Dorre//,6  he 
applied  the  principle  to  the  case  where  an  administrator,  acting 
under  a  grant  of  administration  which  was  afterwards  revoked,  had 
sold  debentures  belonging  to  the  deceased.  He  held  that  the 
rightful  administrator  could  waive  the  conversion,  and  sue  in 
indebitatus  assumpsit  for  their  value,  as  for  money  received  to  his 
use.  In  his  judgment  he  recalled  the  great  doubts  which  eminent 
lawyers  had  had  as  to  the  application  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to 
these  cases."  But  he  made  it  quite  plain  that  these  controversies 
were  then  settled.  "If  two  men  reckon  together,  and  one  over 
pays  the  other,  the  proper  remedy  in  that  case  is  a  special  action 
for  the  money  over  paid,  or  an  account ;  and  yet  in  that  case  you 
constantly  bring  an  indebitatus  assumpsit  for  money  had  and 
received  to  the  plaintiffs  use.  ...  So  the  defendant  in  this  case, 
pretending  to  receive  the  money  the  debentures  were  sold  for  in 
the  right  of  the  intestate,  why  should  he  not  be  answerable  for  it 
to  the  intestate's  administrator."8  And,  at  a  later  day,  he  said 
"  that  he  could  not  see  how  it  differed  from  an  indebitatus  assumpsit 
for  the  profits  of  an  office  by  a  rightful  officer  against  a  wrongful, 

1 "  The  plaintiff  may  charge  the  defendant  as  his  proctor,  and  it  shall  be  no  plea 
for  the  defendant  to  say  that  he  was  not  his  proctor,"  3  Leo.  24. 

8  2  Mod.  95.  3  Arris  v.  Stukeley  (1677)  2  Mod.  at  p.  262. 

4  "  If  this  were  now  an  original  case  we  are  agreed  it  would  by  no  means  lie;  .  .  . 
but  because  judgments  have  been  upon  it,  and  that  on  solemn  arguments,  and  many 
judgments,  though  some  passed  sub  silentio,  yet  others  have  been  debated  and  settled, 
and  particularly  in  the  Exchequer,  we  are  therefore  willing  to  go  the  same  way,"  per 
Scroggs,  C.J.,  delivering  the  opinion  of  the  court  2  Shower,  K.B.,  at  p.  24. 

■  Comb.  447,  cited  above  93  n.  2.  s  2  L<j   Raym.  I2I6. 

These  actions  have  crept  in  by  degrees.  I  remember  in  the  case  of  Mr.  Aston, 
in  a  dispute  about  the  office  of  clerk  to  the  papers  in  this  Court,  there  were  great 
counsel  consulted  with;  and  Sir  William  Jones  and  Mr.  Saunders  were  of  opinion  an 
indebitatus  would  not  lie,  upon  meeting  and  conferring  together,  and  great  consider- 
ation," ibid  at  p.  1217. 

8  Ibid. 


96       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

as  money  had  and  received  by  the  wrongful  officer  to  the  use  of  the 
rightful."1 

(3)   The  beginnings  of  the  modern  law. 

It  is  clear  from  these  cases  that,  though  in  an  indebitatus 
assumpsit  a  promise  to  pay  was  supposed  to  have  been  made,  the 
promise  was  very  much  of  a  fiction.  It  is  clear,  therefore,  that 
Holt's  objections  on  this  score  to  allowing  the  action  for  breaches 
of  bye- laws  and  customary  duties  could  hardly  be  sustained.  The 
action  had  come  to  be  regarded  as  the  proper  remedy  for  a  mass 
of  miscellaneous  duties  imposed  by  law.  But  what  was  the 
principle  upon  which  these  duties  were  thus  enforced  ?  The  form 
of  the  action  implied  that  they  were  enforced  because  the  party 
liable  had  agreed  to  pay.  But  that  was  notoriously  false. 
Blackstone,  it  is  true,  by  the  help  of  the  original  contract,  tried  to 
give  some  colour  to  this  fiction.2  A  person  was  liable  to  be  sued 
in  debt  on  a  judgment  or  a  penal  statute,  or  in  indebitatus 
assumpsit  on  a  bye-law,  because  of  "  an  implied  original  contract 
to  submit  to  the  rules  of  the  community  whereof  we  are  members." 3 
In  other  cases  an  agreement  was  implied  "from  natural  reason 
and  the  just  construction  of  the  law."4  For  instance,  it  is  on  this 
ground  that  we  are  liable  to  pay  for  work  done  at  our  request,  or 
to  pay  over  money  received  to  another's  use,  or  to  remunerate  a 
person  who  has  spent  his  own  money  for  our  benefit  at  our 
request,  or  to  pay  what  is  due  on  an  account  stated,  or  to  show 
adequate  skill  in  any  office  or  employment.  It  is  clear  that 
Blackstone,  in  thus  endeavouring  to  give  colour  to  this  fiction  of 
agreement,  hopelessly  mixed  up  cases  where  there  is  a  real  but 
an  implied  contract,  with  cases  where  there  is  no  real  contract, 
but  merely  an  obligation  implied  by  law — in  other  words,  a  quasi- 
contract.  But  the  fact  that  Blackstone  could  seriously  put  forward 
such  a  theory,  both  illustrates  the  somewhat  haphazard  way  'in 
which  these  various  duties  had  come  to  be  enforced,  either  by  the 
actions  of  debt  or  account,  or  by  successive  expansions  of  various 
forms  of  assumpsit,  and  shows  that,  owing  to  this  haphazard 
development,  the  law  had  not  attained  a  coherent  theory  of  quasi- 
contract. 

It  was  easy  enough  to  see  that  in  many  of  these  cases  the 
obligation,  being  imposed  by  law,  had  nothing  contractual  about 
it.  It  was  obvious,  for  instance,  that  the  obligation  to  make  a 
customary  payment,  or  to  pay  a  penalty  for  the  breach  of  a  bye- 
law,  was  simply  imposed  by  law ;  and  the  same  fact  was  equally 

1  2  Ld.  Raym.  1217.  2  Comm.  iii  158-165. 

3  Ibid  159.  4  Ibid  161. 


QUASI-CONTRACT  97 

obvious  in  many  of  these  cases  in  which  the  law  imposed  an 
obligation  to  pay,  in  order  to  remedy  an  unjust  enrichment.  But 
these  cases  were  numerous  and  varied,  and  the  principle  which 
underlay  them  badly  needed  to  be  stated.  Here  Lord  Mansfield 
had  his  chance.  He  was  not  faced  by  a  coherent  body  of 
principles  like  the  doctrine  of  consideration,1  or  the  rules  as  to 
disseisin,2  or  the  rule  in  Shelley  s  Case?  He  found  an  incoherent 
set  of  rules  stated  in  a  number  of  heterogeneous  cases ;  and  if 
there  was  any  one  principle  at  their  back,  it  was  the  innate  feeling 
of  the  judges  that  it  was  just  and  equitable  that  a  convenient 
remedy  should  be  given  in  these  cases.  This  was  a  situation  with 
which  he  was  eminently  qualified  to  deal.  In  the  passage  in  his 
judgment  in  Moses  v.  Macfarlan*  in  which  he  laid  down  the 
conditions  under  which  an  action  would  lie  for  these  cases  of 
unjust  enrichment,  he  summed  up  and  thereby  gave  precision  to 
the  principle  underlying  the  earlier  cases.  The  actual  decision  in 
that  case  is  erroneous ; 5  but  the  principles  there  laid  down  are 
the  starting  point  of  the  modern  development  of  what  is  the 
largest  and  most  important  part  of  the  law  of  quasi-contract ;  and 
their  acceptance  has  done  much  to  liberalize  the  common  law. 
"  This  kind  of  equitable  action,"  he  said,6  "  to  recover  back  money 
which  ought  not  in  justice  to  be  kept,  is  very  beneficial,  and 
therefore  much  encouraged.  It  lies  only  for  money  which,  ex 
aequo  et  bono,  the  defendant  ought  to  refund :  it  does  not  lie  for 
money  paid  by  the  plaintiff,  which  is  claimed  of  him  as  payable 
in  point  of  honour  and  honesty,  although  it  could  not  have  been 
recovered  from  him  in  any  course  of  law  ;  as  in  payment  of  a  debt 
barred  by  the  statute  of  Limitations,  or  contracted  during  his 
infancy,  or  to  the  extent  of  principal  and  legal  interest  upon  an 
usurious  contract,  or  for  money  fairly  lost  at  play :  because  in  all 
these  cases  the  defendant  may  retain  it  with  a  safe  conscience, 
though  by  positive  law,  he  was  barred  from  recovering.  But  it 
lies  for  money  paid  by  mistake ;  or  upon  a  consideration  which 
happens  to  fail ;  or  for  money  got  through  imposition  (express 
or  implied)  ;  or  extortion  ;  or  oppression  ;  or  an  undue  advantage 
taken  of  the  plaintiffs  situation,  contrary  to  laws  made  for  the 
protection  of  persons  under  those  circumstances.  In  one  word, 
the  gist  of  this  kind  of  action  is,  that  the  defendant,  upon  the 
circumstances  of  the  case,  is  obliged  by  the  ties  of  natural  justice 
and  equity  to  refund  the  money." 

It  was  thus  in  the  action  of  indebitatus  assumpsit  that  the 
larger  part  of  our  modern  law  of  quasi-contract  has  originated. 

1  Above  29-30.  -  Vol.  vii  44.  *  Vol.  iii  109-110. 

4  (1760)  2  Burr.  1005.  5  2  S.L.C.  (10th  ed.)  413.  6  2  Burr,  at  p.  1012. 

VOL.  VIII. — 7 


98       CONTRACT  AND  QUASI-CONTRACT 

But,  as  we  have  seen,1  there  were  also  a  certain  number  of  quasi- 
contractual  obligations  which  had  never  come  within  its  sphere. 
On  a  judgment  only  debt  could  be  brought ;  and  there  were  a 
certain  number  of  obligations  still  only  remediable  by  actions  on 
the  case.  It  is  not  till  forms  of  action  are  things  of  the  past,  that 
the  products  of  these  various  parallel  developments  will  be  able 
to  be  grouped  together  into  a  uniform  law  of  quasi-contract.  It  is 
not  till  these  procedural  changes  have  taken  place  that  the  fiction 
of  a  promise,  and  with  it  the  confusion  between  implied  contracts 
and  contracts  implied  in  law,  will  be  got  rid  of,  and  the  law  of 
quasi-contract  will  be  able  to  emerge  as  a  distinct  branch  of  the 
law. 

We  must  now  turn  to  that  field  of  mercantile  law  in  which 
this  new  law  of  contract  will  necessarily  play  the  most  important 
part,  in  which  it  will  be  developed  in  many  different  directions, 
and  in  which,  as  the  result  of  these  developments,  many  kinds  of 
particular  contracts,  each  governed  by  their  own  peculiar  rules, 
will  grow  up. 

1  Above  8q. 


CHAPTER  IV 

THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

I  HAVE  already  said  something  of  the  manner  in  which  England 
had,  during  this  period,  become  a  commercial  nation.  We  have 
seen  that,  since  the  new  commercial  needs  of  the  modern  English 
state  were  similar  to  the  commercial  needs  of  the  great  mediaeval 
trading  centres  of  Italy  and  South  Western  Europe,  the  commercial 
mechanism  which  had  been  there  developed  spread,  first  to  the 
commercial  cities  of  the  Netherlands,  and  later  to  England ;  and 
that  the  legal  doctrines,  devised  by  the  mediaeval  canonists  and 
civilians  to  give  expression  to  the  forms  and  working  of  this  com- 
mercial mechanism,  and  to  solve  the  problems  to  which  it  gave 
rise,  were  necessarily  received,  together  with  the  commercial 
mechanism,  to  which  they  owed  their  origin  and  development. 
We  have  seen,  therefore,  that  these  doctrines  formed  the  basis  of 
those  new  rules  of  the  Law  Merchant  which  were  making  their 
appearance  in  England  at  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century ; 
and  that,  though  they  were  necessarily  modified  by  their  contact 
with  the  rules  of  English  law,  they  are  the  foundation  upon 
which  modern  mercantile  law  rests  both  in  England  and  elsewhere.1 
In  this  chapter  we  must  consider  the  origins  and  the  English 
development  of  some  of  the  principal  doctrines  of  the  Law  Merchant. 
I  shall  deal,  in  the  first  place,  with  certain  doctrines  of  commercial 
law,  secondly  with  certain  doctrines  of  maritime  law,  and,  thirdly, 
with  a  topic  which  has  close  relations  with  both  commercial  and 
maritime  law — the  topic  of  insurance. 


Commercial  Law 

The  necessity  of  eluding  the  rigid  mediaeval  prohibition  of 
usury  had  a  large  influence  on  the  legal  forms  which  commercial 
ideas  and  institutions  took,  when  they  first  made  their  appearance  ; 
and  the  modification  of  this  prohibition  was  the  condition  preced- 
ent to  the  transition  from  mediaeval  to  modern  commercial  ideas. 

1  Vol.  v  60-154, 
99 


100  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

I  shall  therefore  begin  the  history  of  this  branch  of  the  law  with  a 
short  account  of  the  mediaeval  attitude  towards  usury,  the  gradual 
modification  of  that  attitude  brought  about  by  the  usury  laws,  its 
total  rejection  in  the  nineteenth  century,  and  its  partial  restora- 
tion in  the  present  century.  Usury  having  been  permitted  under 
conditions,  the  modern  mechanism  of  exchange  could  be  freely 
and  rapidly  developed ;  for  much  of  that  mechanism  depends,  to 
borrow  a  phrase  from  Bagehot,  upon  "  the  diffused  habit  of  lending 
things."  l  Thus  we  get  the  rise  and  development  of  negotiable 
instruments  and  banking,  the  formation  of  all  kinds  of  commercial 
societies,  and  some  signs  of  the  future  development  of  the  modern 
law  of  agency.  With  these  topics  I  shall  deal  under  the  four 
following  heads.  At  the  same  time,  and  as  a  result  of  these 
developments,  it  became  necessary  to  make  provision  for  cases 
where  merchants,  either  from  their  fault  or  their  misfortune,  were 
unable  to  meet  the  liabilities  which  the  new  mechanism  of  com- 
merce had  enabled  them  to  incur.  Thus  we  get  the  beginnings  of 
the  law  of  bankruptcy,  with  which  this  part  of  this  chapter  will 
conclude. 

§  i.  Usury  and  the  Usury  Laws2 

At  no  time  can  the  state  be  wholly  indifferent  to  the  use  which 
the  owners  of  property  make  of  their  property.  More  especially 
must  it  interest  itself  in  the  actions  of  those  who,  having  a  sum  of 
ready  money  at  their  disposal,  seek,  without  risk  to  themselves, 
to  exploit  the  needs  of  poorer  or  less  fortunate  men,  and  to  exact 
from  them  a  reward  for  the  loan  of  this  money.  Thus,  at  all  times, 
the  relations  of  the  lenders  of  money  on  onerous  terms  to  those  in 
need  of  pecuniary  assistance,  require  to  be  watched  carefully,  lest 
the  processes  of  the  law  be  used  for  the  purposes  of  the  most 
grievous  oppression.  In  this  country  a  very  short  experience  of 
the  consequences  of  allowing  lenders  and  borrowers  to  make  what 
bargains  they  please  has  been  sufficient  to  demonstrate  this  fact ; 3 
and  this  century  has  seen  the  state  resume  a  control,  which  it  had 
abandoned  under  the  influence  of  the  a  priori  theories  of  Bentham, 

1  Economic  Studies  (Silver  Library  Ed.)  218. 

2  Much  the  best  English  account  of  the  evolution  of  the  mediaeval,  and  the  growth 
of  the  modern  ideas  on  this  subject,  will  be  found  in  Ashley,  Economic  History  vol.  i 
Pt.  I  chap,  iii ;  Pt.  II  chap,  vi ;  the  introduction  to  Tawney's  edition  of  Wilson  on 
Usury  gives  a  good  account  of  the  transition  from  the  mediaeval  ideas  to  those  of  the 
sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  ;  for  a  good  account  of  the  whole  subject,  from  the 
point  of  view  of  foreign  law,  see  Brissaud,  Cours  d'histoire  generale  du  droit  francais 
1422-1434  ;  see  also  Malynes,  Lex  Mercatoria  Part  II  chaps,  x-xv  ;  Bl.  Comm.  ii  454- 
464 ;  Stephen  H.C.L.  iii  194-igg ;  Bellot,  Bargains  with  Money  Lenders  (2nd  ed.) 
1-82. 

3  See  the  evidence  of  Mathew,  J.,  given  to  the  Select  Committee  on  money-lend- 
ing in  1898,  cited  Bellot,  Op.  cit.  70,  71. 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS      101 

and  of  the  pseudo-scientific  laws  of  the  school  of  laissez  /aire 
economists.1  In  this,  as  in  other  cases,  these  so-called  laws  placed 
obstacles  in  the  way  of  necessary  legislative  changes,  some  time 
after  the  purely  temporary  political  and  economic  conditions,  from 
which  they  were  deduced,  had  ceased  to  exist.  - 

We  have  seen  that  in  the  Middle  Ages  the  state,  and  the 
different  communities  through  which  the  power  of  the  state  was 
exercised,  considered  that  they  were  very  much  interested  in  seeing 
that  property  was  used  in  accordance  with  the  current  notions 
of  morality  and  justice.3  And  it  is  clear  that  when  trade  was  in 
its  infancy,  when,  therefore,  there  was  little  opportunity  for  profit- 
able investment,  the  relation  of  lender  and  borrower  must  be  very 
strictly  supervised.  For,  in  such  a  state  of  society,  borrowers  of 
money  were  more  often  than  not  either  the  extravagant  or  the 
needy.  The  money  was  borrowed,  as  Sir  William  Ashley  says, 
not  for  productive  but  for  consumptive  expenditure.4  There  was 
therefore  some  justification,  both  for  Aristotle's  view  that  all 
interest  was  unlawful  because  money  did  not  breed  money,  and 
for  the  literal  acceptance  of  the  Scriptural  prohibitions  of  usury.5 
If  we  remember  these  facts,  we  shall  not  be  surprised  that  the 
church  and  the  canon  law  6  condemned  all  lending  of  money  as  a 
sin ;  that  the  civil  law  and  the  laws  of  the  states  of  Western 
Europe  endorsed  and  sanctioned  this  condemnation ; "  that  all 
transactions  were  carefully  sifted  to  see  whether  they  were  tainted 
with  its  presence ;  and  that  the  prohibition  of  usury  thus  became, 
as  Brissaud  has  said,  the  keystone  of  the  political  economy  of  the 
Middle  Ages.8 

From  the  earliest  times  the  law  of  the  English  state  was  based 


1  Bentham's  Defence  of  Usury  was  published  in  1787  ;  and  Sir  William  Ashley 
has  pointed  out,  in  a  review  of  Mr.  Tawney's  book,  that  Leslie  Stephen  has  said  that 
Bentham's  tract  "  became  one  of  the  sacred  books  of  the  economists." 

2  The  usury  laws  were  repealed  in  1854,  J7i  J8  Victoria  c.  90  ;  the  Money-lenders 
Act  was  passed  in  1900,  63,  64  Victoria  c.  51. 

3  Vol.  ii  468-469  ;  vol.  iv  316-326. 

4  <«  Where  money  was  borrowed  it  was,  in  the  vast  majority  of  cases,  not  for  what 
is  called  productive  expenditure,  but  for  consumptive  ;  not  to  enlarge  the  area  of  tillage, 
or  to  invest  in  trade  or  industry,  but  to  meet  some  sudden  want  due  to  the  frequent 
famines,  or  to  oppressive  taxation,  or  to  extravagance.  The  money  that  was  lent  was 
money  for  which  it  would  otherwise  have  been  exceedingly  difficult  to  secure  an 
investment.  The  alternative  to  lending  was  allowing  it  to  remain  idle,"  Ashley,  op. 
cit.  i  Ft-  II  435  ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1423- 1424. 

5  Ethics  v;  Politics  1.  10;  Luke  vi  35;  Cunningham,  Industry  and  Commerce 
i  252  n.  1 ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  chap.  x. 

6  See  Clement  V.'s  canon  of  1311,  cited  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt  I  150-151. 

7  Ibid  Pt.  II  382-383 ;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1425-1426. 

8  Op.  cit.  1424 — "  Les  casuistes  cherchent  a  le  proscrire  partout ;  par  suite  de  leur 
intransigeance,  la  defense  de  l'usure  prend  une  extension  invraisemblable,  et  devient 
comme  la  clef  de  voute  de  l'economie  politique  du  moyen  age ;  vente,  payement, 
dommages  intgrets,  society,  banque,  lettre  de  change,  autant  de  matieres  ou  on  s'en 
pre-occupe  particulierement." 


102  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

upon  these  ideas.1  Glanvil  tells  us  that  usury  was  both  a  sin  and 
a  crime.  In  the  usurer's  lifetime  he  was  dealt  with  by  the  ecclesi- 
astical courts  as  a  sinner ;  but,  if  he  died  unrepentant,  the  king 
asserted  a  claim  to  his  goods.2  This  was  also  the  law  in  Bracton's 
day  ; 3  and  it  was  restated  in  1 341.  A  statute  passed  in  that  year 
enacted  that,  "  The  king  and  his  heirs  should  have  the  cognisance 
of  the  usurers  dead  ;  and  that  the  Ordinaries  of  Holy  Church  have 
the  cognisance  of  the  usurers  in  life,  as  to  them  appertaineth,  to 
make  compulsion  by  the  censures  of  Holy  Church  for  the  sin,  and 
to  make  restitution  of  the  usuries  taken  against  the  laws  of  Holy 
Church.4 

As  we  might  expect,  the  temptation  to  fall  into  this  sin  was 
felt  most  keenly  in  the  great  commercial  towns.  In  1363  the  city 
of  London,  encouraged  thereto  by  the  king,5  issued  an  ordinance 
against  it;6  and  in  1 391  further  provisions  were  made.7  The 
object  of  the  latter  provisions  was  to  declare  more  precisely  what 
kinds  of  contract  were  usurious ; 8  and  it  was  further  enacted  that 
brokers,  through  whom  such  bargains  were  usually  negotiated, 
should  be  obliged  to  take  an  oath,  and  to  give  ^100  as  a  security, 
that  they  would  not  meddle  in  any  usurious  transactions.9  The 
case  of  Ralph  Cornwaille,  which  occurred  in  1377,  shows  that  this 
legislation  was  no  dead  letter ; 10  and,  that  it  was  in  accordance 
with  the  public  opinion  of  the  day,  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  in 
1376  the  Commons  petitioned  that  the  ordinances  against  usury 
made  by  the  city  of  London  should  be  enforced  in  all  other  towns.11 
As  late  as  1487  the  legislature  passed  two  statutes  on  the  lines  of 
these  ordinances.  The  first  made  all  "bargayns  groundyt  in 
usurye  "  void,  and  subjected  those  who  made  them  to  a  penalty  of 
,£100,  in  addition  to  any  punishment  which  might  be  inflicted  by 

1  The  apocryphal  laws  of  Edward  the  Confessor  c.  37  (Lieberman,  Die  Gesetze 
der  Angelsachsen  i  668)  treated  usury  as  a  crime — "  si  aliquis  inde  probatus  esset 
omnes  possesuones  sua;  perderet  et  pro  ex  lege  haberttur." 

2  Bk.  vii  16 — "  Usurarii  vero  omnes  res,  sive  testatus  sive  inttstatus  decesserit, 
domini  Regis  sunt ;  vivus  autem  non  solet  aliquis  de  crimine  usurae  appellari  nee 
convinci.  ...  Si  quis  aliquo  tempore  usurarius  fuerit  in  vita  sua,  et  super  hoc  in 
patria  publice  defamatus;  si  tamen  a  delicto  ipso  ante  mortem  suam  destiterit  et 
penitentiam  ejerit,  pest  mortem  ipsius  ille  vel  res  ejus  lege  usurarii  minime  censebun- 
tur  "  ;  cp.  Dialogus  de  Scaccario,  Stubbs,  Sel.  Ch.  (6th  ed.)  229. 

:i  At  ff.  116b,  117.  4i5  Edward  III.  st.  1  c.  5. 

5  Liber  Albus  (R.S.)  iii  142,  143  ;  for  the  French  text  see  ibid  i  267,  268. 

6  Ibid  iii  143-146;  i  368-371.  7  Ibid  iii  161-163  ;  i  399-401. 

8"  Whereas  the  same  Ordinance  (that  of  1363)  is  too  obscure  and  it  is  not  com- 
prised or  declared  therein  in  especial  what  is  usury  or  unlawful  chevisance,"  ibid  iii 
162. 

9  Ibid  iii  163. 

10  Ibid  i  394-399 ;  see  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  i  360-361,  for  a  full  account  of  this 
case ;  a  loan  of  £10  was  negotiated  through  brokers  for  which  the  lender  wished  to 
charge  80%,  and,  on  non-payment,  he  sued  lor  the  money ;  on  complaint  to  the  Mayor 
and  aldermen,  Ra'ph  Cornwaille,  the  borrower,  was  freed  from  his  obligations,  and  the 
lender  was  imprisoned  till  he  had  paid  double  the  interest  as  a  penalty  to  the  city. 

11  R.P.  ii  350  (50  Ed.  III.  no.  158). 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS      103 

the  ecclesiastical  courts.1  The  second  inflicted  penalties  on  brokers 
who  made  these  usurious  contracts.2 

At  the  latter  part  of  the  fifteenth  and  in  the  sixteenth  centuries 
economic  conditions  were  changing.3  The  growth  of  trade  was 
making  it  clear  that  traders  could  make  a  productive  use  of  bor- 
rowed money,  and  that  therefore  a  payment  for  the  use  of  borrowed 
money  might  be  advantageous  both  to  the  parties  to  the  contract  and 
to  the  state.  The  result  was,  not  the  repeal  of  the  general  prohibi- 
tion of  usury,  but  the  growth  of  a  large  number  of  rules,  which 
were  designed  to  distinguish  between  those  payments  for  the  use 
of  money  which  were  usurious  and  illegal,  from  those  which  were 
permissible. 

The  basis  of  these  rules  was  the  distinction  drawn,  as  early  as 
the  first  half  of  the  thirteenth  century,  between  a  mere  payment 
for  the  use  of  money,  and  a  payment  made  to  compensate  the 
lender  for  some  loss  actually  occasioned  by  non-payment  {damnum 
emergens),  or  for  failure  to  realize  some  expected  gain  in  conse- 
quence of  his  not  having  the  money  in  hand  {lucrum  cessans)}  A 
payment  on  account  of  damnum  emergens  was  recognized  as  valid 
by  Aquinas ; 5  and,  as  the  opportunities  for  profitable  investment 
increased,  a  payment  on  account  of  lucrum  cessans  gradually  came 
to  be  regarded  as  lawful.  Sir  William  Ashley  says  that  in  the 
fifteenth  century  its  legality  was  generally  accepted  by  the  best 
theologians.0  But  it  should  be  noted  that  the  loss  must  actually 
be  proved ; 7  and  it  was  necessary  that,  in  the  first  instance,  the 
loan  should  have  been  gratuitous.  Technically,  the  payment  was 
made,  not  for  the  loan,  but  for  non-payment  of  a  gratuitous  loan 
at  the  date  promised.8  Gradually,  however,  in  the  case  of  traders, 
the  loss  came  to  be  presumed ;  and,  with  the  shortening  of  the 
period  of  the  gratuitous  loan,  the  making  of  it  gratuitously  for  a 
short  period  came  to  be  a  mere  formality.9  But  this  development 
did  not  take  place  till  after  the  close  of  the  mediaeval  period ; 10 

1 3  Henry  VII.  c.  5.  2  3  Henry  VII.  c.  6.  3  Vol.  iv  316-319. 

■•Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  399;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1427. 

5  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  399. 

c"  Even  some  of  the  contemporaries  of  Aquinas  among  the  canonists  had  held 
this  opinion;  so  that  during  the  following  century,  the  fourteenth,  it  could  hardly  be 
regarded  as  distinctly  under  the  ban  of  the  Church ;  and  in  the  fifteenth  it  was  cer- 
tainly very  generally  accepted  by  the  best  theologians,"  ibid  401. 

7  Siraccha,  De  Mercatura,  Pt.  IV.,  De  contractibus  mercatorum  §  3  (Tractatus 
Universi  Juris  vi  Pt.  I.  298b)  says,  "  Probare  debes  quod  mercator  habuit  prae  mani- 
bus  mercts  quasdam  quibus  fuisset  lucratus  .  .  .  ,  et  quia  caruit  pecunia,  non  potuit 
emere,  vel  alio  modo  potuit  constare,  quod  si  habuisset  illam  pecunhm,  certe  lucratus 
essat." 

8  Ashley,  op.  cit  i  Pt.  II.  401,  402.  9  Ibid  402. 

10  Ibid  403  ;  Malynes,  Lex  Mercatoria  243,  clearly  states  the  view  of  his  own  day 
on  this  matter — "  A  man  may  take  a  benefit  for  his  money  two  manner  of  ways,  which 
is  ex  damno  habito,  when  he  hath  sustained  a  loss,  or  ex  lucre  ccssante,  when  his  bene- 
fit or  profit  hath  been  taken  away  or  prevented  for  want  of  his  money,  which  he  might 
have  bestowed  in  some  wares  to  furnish  his  shop  at  convenient  time,  and  in  both  these 
the  party  is  not  active  but  passive." 


104  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and,  by  that  time,  the  application  of  the  strict  mediaeval  principle 
had  been  weakened  by  the  manner  in  which  this  idea  of  compensa- 
tion for  loss  had  been  applied  to  render  legal  many  kinds  of  com- 
mercial contracts. 

One  of  the  commonest  of  the  mediaeval  commercial  contracts 
was  the  Commenda — a  form  of  societas,  and  the  direct  ancestor  of 
those  limited  partnerships  of  continental  law  which  have  lately  been 
introduced  into  this  country.1  A,  a  merchant,  stays  at  home,  and 
entrusts  goods  or  money  to  another  that  he  may  trade  with  them 
in  foreign  lands,  in  return  for  a  share  of  the  profits  resulting  from 
this  trade ;  or,  A,  the  travelling  merchant,  borrows  capital  from 
the  merchant  at  home,  that  he  may  trade  with  it,  in  return  for  a 
share  of  the  profits.2  In  these  cases  the  risk  run  by  the  lender 
entitled  him  to  a  payment  for  the  use  of  his  capital.  The  London 
ordinance  of  1391  makes  it  quite  clear  that  such  lending  for  gain, 
if  accompanied  by  risk,  was  not  punishable  as  usury.3  Exactly 
the  same  considerations  applied  to  loans  on  bottomry.  The 
lender  risked  the  loss  of  his  money  if  the  ship  did  not  arrive  safely, 
and  for  this  risk  he  was  entitled  to  be  paid.4  Insurance  also  could 
be  similarly  justified. &  In  all  these  cases  payment  was  made,  not 
for  the  loan  of  money,  but  for  the  loss  or  risk  of  loss  run  by  the 
lender.  It  was  only  if  the  lender  contracted  to  receive  payment 
for  his  money  in  any  event  that  he  fell  under  the  ban  of  the  law. 

A  further  step  was  made  towards  the  weakening  of  the  general 
principle  when  men  began  to  reflect  upon  these  various  transac- 
tions which  were  thus  held  to  be  lawful,  and  to  extend  them  by 
inference  and  deduction.  We  see  an  illustration  of  this  in  the 
contractus  trinus  of  the  late  fifteenth  century,  which  distinguished 
theologians  and  canonists  of  the  sixteenth  century  asserted  to  be 
legal.6  Sir  William  Ashley  has  very  clearly  described  this  con- 
tract;  and  I  shall  copy  his  description.7  "An  ordinary  contract 
of  partnership  sharing  risk  and  profit  was  justifiable ;  so  was  also 
a  contract  of  assurance.  A  man  could  enter  into  partnership 
with  B  ;  and  he  could  insure  himself  with  C  against  the  loss  of 
his  capital ;  and  he  could  insure  himself  with  U  against  fluctua- 
tions in  the  rate  of  profit  [by  the  machinery  of  selling  his  uncertain 

1  Below  195-197. 

2  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  413-415  ;  as  Brissaud  has  said,  op.  cit.  1426,  "  On  ne 
preta  plus,  mais  on  associa." 

3  Liber  Albus  (R.S.)  iii  161 — "  If  any  person  shall  lend  or  put  into  the  hands  of 
any  person  gold  or  silver  to  receive  gain  thereby,  or  a  promise  for  certain  without  risk, 
let  such  person  have  the  punishment  for  usurers." 

4  Below  261-263. 

5  Below  275-276;  cp.  Straccha,  De  Assecuratione,  Introd.  §§  43,  44,  Tractatus 
Universi  Juris  vi  Pt.  I.  p.  360b. 

6  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  440-447  ;  see  Scaccia,  De  Commercio  et  Cambiis  §  3 
Gloss.  3  no.  36. 

7  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  440-441 ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1427  n.  4. 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS      105 

profit  for  a  less  but  certain  profit].1  If  all  this  was  morally  justi- 
fiable,, why  should  not  A  make  the  three  contracts  with  the  same 
man  B  ?  or,  to  put  it  in  a  different  way,  why  should  not  A  place  a 
certain  sum  in  the  hands  of  B,  agreeing  to  receive  only  a  low  rate 
of  interest,  in  consideration  of  a  promise  on  B's  part  (a)  to  restore 
the  capital,  and  {b)  to  pay  a  particular  rate  of  interest  in  any  case, 
whether  the  gains  were  high,  low,  or  even  absent."  It  is  clear, 
as  Sir  William  Ashley  says,2  that  "  under  the  forms  of  partner- 
ship, the  contract  had  become  nothing  more  nor  less  than  a  loan 
on  interest ;  the  essential  element  in  partnership,  participation  in 
risk,  had  been  contracted  away." 

Another  device,  whereby  a  landowner  could  in  substance 
borrow  money  at  interest,  was  the  creation  of  a  rent  charge  on  his 
property ; 3  or,  as  we  have  seen,  the  grant  of  a  lease  by  the 
borrower  to  the  lender  at  a  nominal  rent.4  This  was  never 
accounted  usury — possibly  because  the  transaction  was,  in  early 
times,  regarded  as  the  creation  or  conveyance  of  a  res,  and  there- 
fore quite  distinct  from  a  loan.5  It  was  only  if  the  creditor,  to 
whom  land  had  been  thus  conveyed  in  mortgage,  took  the  profits 
of  the  land  and  did  not  set  them  off  against  the  debt,  that  the 
transaction  was  usurious.6  In  the  latter  part  of  the  fifteenth 
century  the  nature  of  these  transactions  was  more  closely  analysed. 
In  substance  they  looked  very  like  loans  of  money  at  interest." 
The  landowner,  or  the  shop-keeper,  who  created  a  redeemable  rent 
charge  on  his  property  in  return  for  a  capital  sum  of  money,  in 
substance  borrowed  that  capital  sum  at  interest8  But  the  church 
held  that,  so  long  as  these  charges  were  only  created  upon  bona 
stabilia  which  produced  an  income,  so  long  as  the  rent  charge 
bore  a  reasonable  relation  to  the  capital  sum  paid  for  it,  and  so 
long  as  the  debtor  retained  the  right  to  redeem,  the  transaction 

1  For  the  device  of  using  the  machinery  of  a  sale  to  effect  an  insurance  see  below 
277-278 ;  the  contract  consisted,  as  Brissaud  shows,  of  contracts  of  partnership,  in- 
surance, and  sale. 

2  Op.  cit  441. 

3  Ibid  405-411 ;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1429-1434 ;  cp.  also  Select  Pleas  in  the  Star 
Chamber  (S.S.)  i  lxxxiii-lxxxv. 

4  Vol.  iii  129. 

*  As  Brissaud  says,  op.  cit.  1429 — These  rents  "  ont  commence  par  etre  un  mode 
d'exploitation  des  terres  et  nullement  une  operation  de  credit "  ;  "la  rente  apparaissait 
comme  un  etre  moral  distinct  des  arrgrages,  produisant  des  revenues  a  la  facon  d'un 
fonds  de  terre,  '  de  duree  a  tourjours ' ;  lorsque  le  d£biteur  remboursait  le  capital  qu'il 
avait  recu,  on  disait  qu'il  rachetait  la  rente,"  ibid  1432. 

*  Vol.  iii  128 ;  Glanvil  x  8  ;  Dialogus  de  Scaccario,  Stubbs,  Sel.  Ch.  229,  230. 

7  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  40S-409. 

8  "  The  canonist  theory  put  no  obstacle  in  the  way  either  of  a  landed  proprietor, 
or  of  an  artisan  with  a  shop  or  stall  and  the  trade  rights  that  usually  went  with  it, 
who  wished  to  borrow  capital  to  put  into  his  land  or  his  business  by  means  of  the 
sale  of  a  redeemable  rent  charge,"  ibid  410-41 1 ;  cp.  Select  Cases  in  the  Star  Chamber 
(S.S.)  i  lxxxiv. 


106  THR  LAW  MERCHANT 

was  lawful.1  It  is  perhaps  possible  that  this  last  condition  may 
have  had  some  influence  upon  the  growth  of  the  doctrine  as  to  re- 
demption which,  in  the  sixteenth  century,  the  Court  of  Chancery 
was  beginning  to  make  an  essential  part  of  all  mortgage  transac- 
tions.2 

If  we  look  at  these  various  methods  by  which  in  substance  it 
had  become  possible  to  borrow  money  at  interest ;  if  we  remember 
that  many  of  the  Italian  states  borrowed  money  and  contracted  to 
pay  interest  on  their  loans ; 3  that  in  many  of  the  Italian  com- 
mercial towns  litigants  were  prohibited  from  invoking  the  aid  of 
the  laws  against  usury ; 4  that  the  Franciscans  had  in  some  of 
these  states  established,  with  the  approval  of  the  church,  montes 
pietatis,  or  funds  from  which  loans  were  made  to  the  needy  in 
return  for  a  low  rate  of  interest 5 — we  shall  see  that  many  inroads 
from  many  different  sides  had,  at  the  close  of  the  mediaeval 
period,  been  made  on  the  general  principle  that  all  usury  was 
sinful. 

But  the  principle  was  still  accepted.  Usury  was  still  de- 
nounced in  the  old  terms ;  and  those  who  wished  to  evade  the 
law  made  use  of  various  devices  to  cloak  their  real  intentions." 
We  shall  see  that  when  the  legality  of  the  contract  of  insurance 
was  in  doubt,  recourse  was  had  to  the  expedient  of  a  sale  and 
resale  to  cloak  the  real  bargain  ; "  and  that  the  machinery  of  the 
contract  of  exchange  or  cambium  was  largely  used  to  effect  the 
same  object.8     We  are  reminded  of  the  various  expedients  which 

1  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  409,  410. 

2  Vol.  v.  293,  330-331 ;  vol.  vi  664 ;  this  condition  seems  to  be  much  more  closely 
connected  with  the  equitable  prohibition  of  clogging  the  equity  of  redemption  than  the 
general  law  against  usury,  ibid  n.  6. 

3  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  447-448  ;  below  179,  207-208. 

4  Vol.  v  80  n.  2;  cp.  Bensa,  Histoire  du  Contrat  d' Assurance  au  moyen  age 
(Translated  by  Valery)  4 — "  meme  a  diverses  reprises  les  l^gislateurs  municipaux 
s'efforcerent  d'empecher  que  les  prescriptions  du  droit  canon  .  .  .  fussent  appliquees 
ou  meme  fussent  seulement  invoqu£es  ;  ils  menacaient  en  effet  de  peines  rigoureuses 
quiconque  chercherait  a  s'en  prevaloir  pour  se  soustraire  aux  suites  de  ses  engage- 
ments "  ;  we  may  note  that  in  the  Select  Cases  in  Chancery  (S.S.)  no.  95  (1408)  we 
see  an  Englishman  at  Verona  doing  a  money-lending  business  with  Englishmen 
visiting  that  city. 

6  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  449-451 ;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  1427  n.  7  ;  cp.  Malynes,  op. 
cit.  Pt.  II.  chap,  xiii  for  an  account  of  the  Mons  Pietatis  at  Bruges, — an  institution 
which  he  would  have  liked  to  see  established  in  London  ;  he  also  advocated,  ibid  235, 
a  strict  regulation  of  pawnbrokers,  which  regulation  had  been  already  begun  by  the 
statute  1  James  I.  c.  21. 

6  For  an  interesting  case  of  a  fictitious  contract  made  to  conceal  usury  see  a  bill 
in  Chancery  of  Edward  IV.'s  reign,  printed  by  Tawney  and  Power,  Economic 
Documents,  ii  133-134. 

7  Below  277-278. 

8  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  426-427;  cp.  Liber  Albus  iii  147 — a  letter  under  the 
Privy  Seal  of  1366  says  that,  "  many  merchants  and  others  dwelling  in  our  city  of 
Lon:Jon,  colourably  and  subtly  have  made,  and  do  make  from  day  to  day,  divers 
exchanges  of  money  and  of  other  things  that  do  not  concern  the  dealings  of  lawful 
merchandize  "  ;   the  practice  under  the  name  of  "  dry  exchange  "  is  alluded  to  in 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS      107 

can  be  used  at  the  present  day  to  evade  the  laws  which  declare 
wagering  contracts  to  be  void.  Such  expedients  are  the  best 
evidence  of  the  existence  of  the  general  prohibition.  But,  it 
may  be  asked,  why  was  it  that  this  general  prohibition  was  still 
maintained,  seeing  that  the  exceptions  to,  and  the  evasions  of  it, 
now  covered  so  much  ground?  No  doubt  this  was  partly  due  to 
the  authority  of  the  church ;  but,  as  Sir  William  Ashley  has 
pointed  out,  there  was  a  substantial  justification  for  this  use  of  the 
church's  authority.  No  doubt  in  the  trading  centres  the  modifica- 
tions of  the  rule  almost  went  to  the  length  of  repealing  it ;  but 
the  merchants  were  but  a  small  fraction  of  the  people  who  owned 
allegiance  to  and  sought  protection  from  the  church.  "  By  far 
the  greater  part  of  the  population  of  Western  Europe  continued 
to  be  engaged  in  the  old  unchanging  pursuits  of  agriculture  :  a 
declaration  that  payment  could  be  taken  for  the  loan  of  money 
would  have  meant  the  delivering  them  into  the  hands  of  the 
spoiler.  The  church,  caring  for  the  masses  of  the  people,  for  the 
weak  and  stupid,  might  think  it  well  to  maintain  a  prohibition 
which  imposed  no  restriction  on  the  activity  of  the  traders  in  the 
towns,  who  were  well  enough  off  to  take  care  of  themselves. 
The  original  prohibition  had  really  aimed  at  preventing  the 
oppression  of  the  weak  by  the  economically  strong.  The  gradual 
exemption  from  the  prohibition  of  methods  of  employing  money 
which  did  not  involve  oppression,  instead  of  obscuring  the  original 
principle,  may  be  said  to  have  brought  it  out  more  clearly."1 
That  this  was  the  point  of  view  taken  by  the  English  legislator 
we  can  see  from  a  statute  of  1495,2  which  replaced  that  passed  in 
1487.  Its  object  was  to  distinguish  between  cases  where  a  reward 
could  lawfully  be  taken  for  a  loan  and  cases  where  it  could  not. 
Thus  it  allows,  "  lawful  penalties  for  the  non-payment  of  money 
lent"  It  condemns  the  sale  of  goods  and  their  repurchase  for  a 
less  sum,  only  if  the  transaction  was  with  a  person  "  in  necessity." 
It  condemns  a  loan  of  money  in  return  for  the  rents  and  profits  of 
land,  only  if  the  lender  incurred  no  "  adventure,"  or  if  he  was  to 
have  the  rents  and  profits  of  the  land  for  a  time  certain.3^ 

3  Henry  VII.  c.  5  ;  Tawney,  op.  cit.  73-74  ;  as  Bensa  says,  op.  cit.  8,  "  Le  change  £tait 
bien  moins  un  contrat  sui  generis  qu'une  forme  ou  mieux  encore  un  deguisement  dont 
ou  revetait  toutes  sortes  de  transactions  pecur.iaries  pour  les  mettre  a  l'abri  des  lois 
port£es  contre  Tusure  "  ;  see  below  126-130  for  the  contract  of  cambium. 

1  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  438-439.  These  principles  continued  to  be  applied  to  the 
types  of  credit  transactions  entered  into  by  peasants  and  small  masters,  Tawney,  op. 
cit.  17-30,  and  by  needy  gentlemen,  ibid  31-42;  the  former  class  of  borrowers  were 
protected  till  1854  by  the  usury  laws,  and  the  latter  class  were  also  protected  by  the 
growth  of  the  equitable  doctrines  as  to  mortgages,  and  as  to  catching  bargains. 

2  n  Henry  VII.  c.  8. 

3  Above  105-106  ;  the  current  view  of  the  usurious  character  of  such  dealings  in 
land  is  illustrated  by  two  cases  of  29  and  31  Henry  VIII.  abridged  by  Brooke,  Ab. 
Usurie  pi.  1  and  2 ;  cp.  Burton's  Case  (1592)  5  Co.  Rep.  69a ;  Sharpley  v.  Hurrel 
(1609)  Cro.  Jac.  208 ;  Roberts  v.  Tremayne  (1619)  ibid  507. 


108  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

When  this  stage  had  been  reached,  it  was  inevitable  that 
further  developments  should  be  made.  Clearly  all  loans  of  money 
at  interest  could  not  be  condemned.  The  methods  employed  to 
evade  the  penalties  for  usury  were  coming  to  be  merely  colourable 
devices.  The  maintenance  of  the  law,  which  rendered  these 
devices  necessary,  increased  the  lender's  risk,  and  therefore  the 
interest  required  by  the  borrower.  The  legislator  was,  as  we 
have  seen,  coming  to  regard  commercial  dealings  not  so  much 
from  the  point  of  view  of  their  moral  rectitude  as  from  the  point 
of  view  of  their  bearing  upon  the  power  of  the  state  ; *  and  from 
this  point  of  view  it  was  clearly  desirable,  in  the  interests  of 
commercial  development,  to  encourage  loans  of  capital  by  per- 
mitting interest  to  be  taken.2  On  the  other  hand,  it  was  clear  that 
to  leave  persons  free  to  make  what  loans  they  pleased  at  any 
interest  they  pleased  would  lead  to  oppression.  As  Bacon  said, 
"  two  things  are  to  be  reconciled :  the  one  that  the  tooth  of  usurie 
be  grinded,  that  it  bite  not  too  much ;  the  other  that  there  be  left 
open  a  meanes  to  invite  moneyed  men  to  lend  to  the  merchants 
for  the  continuing  and  quickening  of  trade." 3  The  reconciliation 
of  these  two  things  "produced  a  controversy  hardly  less  acute 
than  that  which  accompanied  the  rise  of  machine  industry  in 
England  two  centuries  later."4 

In  1535  Thomas  Cromwell  contemplated  drawing  a  statutory 
distinction  between  cases  in  which  the  expedients  which  enabled 
interest  to  be  contracted  for  were  used  as  a  mere  cloak  for  usury, 
and  cases  in  which  the  parties  were  engaged  in  a  bona  fide 
commercial  transaction.5  But  the  project  came  to  nothing. 
Probably  it  was  found  to  be  impracticable.  In  1 545  a  less  logical 
but  more  workable  solution  was  devised.  A  statute  passed  in  that 
year 6  saved  the  face  of  the  older  doctrine  by  a  condemnation  of 
usury  in  the  old  terms,  but  at  the  same  time  recognized  the  new 
conditions  by  repealing  all  the  former  statutes,  and  by  permitting 
persons  to  lend  money  at  a  rate  of  interest  not  exceeding  ten 
per  cent  without  being  liable  for  the  penalties  for  usury.7     Any 

1  Vol.  iv  318. 

2  Bacon  says  in  his  Essay  on  Usury  that,  "  howsoever  usury  in  some  respects 
hindereth  merchandising,  yet  in  some  other  it  advanceth  it ;  for  it  is  certain  that  the 
greatest  part  of  trade  is  driven  by  young  merchants  upon  borrowing  at  interest ;  so  as 
if  the  usurer  either  call  in  or  keep  back  his  money,  there  will  ensue  presently  a  great 
stand  of  trade"  ;  cp.  Tawney,  op.  cit.  43  seqq. 

3  Essay  on  Usury.  4  Tawney,  op.  cit.  105. 

5  L.  and  P.  ix  ii  no.  725 — "  that  an  act  may  be  made  against  usury  which  is 
cloaked  by  pretence  of  law." 

6  37  Henry  VIII.  c.  9. 

7  The  preamble  states  that,  "  before  this  tyme  diverse  and  sondrie  Actes  .  .  . 
have  bene  .  .  .  made  for  the  punyshment  of  Usurye,  beinge  a  Thinge  unlawfull  .  .  . 
which  Actes  .  .  .  ben  soe  obscure  and  darke  .  .  .  and  upon  the  same  soe  many 
doubts  .  .  .  have  risen  .  .  .  and  the  same  acts  .  .  .  bene  of  so  litle  force  and  effect, 
that  by  reason  thereof  litle  or  noe  punyshment  hath  ensued  to  thoffendors  of  the  same, 
but  rather  hath  encouraged  them  to  use  the  same." 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS       109 

attempt  to  evade  the  act  by  sales  and  repurchases,  or  by  mortgages 
in  return  for  rents  and  profits,  was  punished  by  the  forfeiture  of 
treble  the  value  of  the  property  sold,  or  the  profits  contracted  for  ; 
and,  in  addition,  fine  and  imprisonment  In  1551-15521  this 
statute  was  repealed — the  Protestants  were  no  more  inclined  to 
favour  usury  than  the  Catholics.  It  was  declared  that  usury  was 
utterly  prohibited  by  the  word  of  God,  and  the  taking  of  any  kind 
of  interest  was  forbidden  in  the  most  comprehensive  terms. 

But  in  Elizabeth's  reign  other  counsels  prevailed.  Protestant 
opinion  had  wavered.  Though  Luther  had  supported  the  general 
prohibition,  Melancthon  had  seen  that  traders  must  be  allowed  to 
borrow  at  a  moderate  rate  of  interest ; 2  and  Calvin,  though  not 
perhaps  prepared  to  go  quite  so  far  as  Melancthon,  admitted  that 
there  might  be  circumstances  in  which  the  taking  of  interest  was 
lawful.3  Among  both  Protestants  and  Catholics,  "the  moral 
distinction  was  tending  more  and  more  to  become  one  between 
excessive  demand  and  moderate  demand,  rather  than  between 
gratuitous  and  non-gratuitous  loan."4  In  1  571  5  a  statute  was 
passed  repealing  the  statute  of  Edward  VI.,  and  reviving  that  of 
Henry  VIII.  Usury  was  still  branded  as  a  detestable  sin  punish- 
able in  the  ecclesiastical  courts  ;  and  in  the  temporal  courts  it  was 
declared  to  be  an  offence  which  rendered  those  guilty  of  it  liable  to 
the  penalties  of  a  praemunire.  But  it  was  provided  that  no  one 
should  be  liable  to  these  punishments  if  the  rate  of  interest  did  not 
exceed  ten  per  cent6  On  the  other  hand,  though  a  person  who 
took  less  than  ten  per  cent  was  not  liable  to  these  punishments, 

1 5,6  Edward  VI.  c.  20;  Crowley,  Information  to  Parliament  (E.E.T.S.)  172-174, 
voices  the  prevailing  conservative  view;  cp.  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  465. 

2  Ibid  456-458. 

3  Among  the  conditions  laid  down  by  Calvin  as  justifying  usury  are  the  follow- 
ing : — "  That  usury  should  not  be  demanded  from  men  in  need ;  nor  is  it  lawful  to 
force  any  man  to  pay  usury  who  is  oppressed  by  need  or  calamity"  ;  and  that,  "he 
who  receives  a  loan  on  usury  should  make  at  least  as  much  for  himself  by  his  labour 
and  care  as  he  obtains  who  gives  the  loan,"  cited  ibid  459;  as  Mr.  Tawney  says,  op. 
cit.  in,  Calvin  approached  the  question  from  the  standpoint  of  a  man  of  affairs  who 
assumed  the  existence  of  capital  and  credit,  and  wished  to  moralize  the  commercial 
institutions  of  his  day;  his  "indulgence  to  moderate  interest,  like  Adam  Smith's 
individualism,  was  remembered  when  the  qualifications  surrounding  it  were 
forgotten,"  ibid  120. 

4  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  It.  451 ;  cp.  Grotius,  De  jure  Belli  et  Pacis  ii  12.  22  (cited 
Bl.  Comm.  ii  456) — "  If  the  compensation  allowed  by  law  does  not  exceed  the 
proportion  of  the  hazard  run,  or  the  want  felt,  by  the  loan,  it's  allowance  is  neither 
repugnant  to  the  revealed  nor  the  natural  law :  but  if  it  exceeds  those  bounds,  it  is  then 
oppressive  usury ;  and  though  municipal  laws  may  give  it  impunity,  they  never  can 
make  it  just." 

s  13  Elizabeth  c.  8,  made  perpetual  39  Elizabeth  c.  18 ;  for  an  attempt  to  legislate 
in  this  way  in  1563  see  Tawney,  op.  cit.  158 ;  for  some  cases  on  the  statute  see  Burton's 
Case  (1592)  5  Co.  Rep.  oga ;  Clayton's  Case  (1595)  ibid  70a;  cp.  Cunningham,  op.  cit. 
y  153.  154. 

'That  no  distinction  was  drawn  by  the  Act  of  Edward  VI.  between  different  rates 
of  interest  was  noted  in  13  Elizabeth  c.  8  as  one  of  the  reasons  for  repealing  it. 


110  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

he  was  liable  to  forfeit  the  interest  if  proceedings  were  taken  to 
recover  it.1  This  clause  in  the  Act  seems  to  have  been  a  dead 
letter ; 2  and  it  was  not  repeated  in  the  Act  of  1623,  which  lowered 
the  rate  of  interest  to  eight  per  cent.3 

It  was  far  from  being  a  logical  rule — "you  may  perceive,"  said 
Malynes,4  "what  laws  and  prohibitions  are  made  against  usury; 
and  nevertheless  the  practice  of  it  is  most  usual  in  many  kingdoms 
and  commonweals,  and  the  laws  are  also  made  accordingly  "  ;  and 
it  was  naturally  distasteful  to  the  rigid  moralists.  Their  views 
found  expression  in  the  treatise  on  usury,  written  in  1  569  by  Dr. 
Wilson,  Master  of  Requests,5  and  first  published  in  1572.6  "At 
the  last,"  he  says,7  "you  come  to  a  rate,  and  woulde  in  any  wise 
have  ten  or  twelve  upon  the  hundred  eyther  appointed  or 
tollerated.  .  .  .  But  I  am  not  of  your  mynde,  because  God  is 
against  you  and  therefore  1  do  abhorre  all  toleracion  of  usurie  .  .  . 
but  rather  I  would  wishe  that  there  were  as  straite  lawes  to  forbid 
usurie  as  there  bee  to  forbid  felony  or  murther."  On  the  other 
hand,  following  the  mediaeval  distinction,  he  would  allow  a  payment 
of  interest  for  loss  sustained  as  distinct  from  usury.8  That  Wilson 
took  the  old-fashioned  view  is,  I  think,  due  to  the  fact  that  he  was 
an  Anglican,  a  canonist,  and  an  ambassador.  As  an  Anglican,  he 
naturally  magnified,  as  many  Anglican  writers  magnified,9  the 
literal  words  of  the  Bible,  and  he  was  naturally  inclined  to  oppose 
the  more  liberal  opinions  of  Calvin.  As  a  canonist,  he  was  inclined 
to  stress  those  texts  of  the  canon  law  which  were  in  harmony  with 
the  words  of  the  Bible — they  were  the  parts  of  the  canon  law 
which,  being  in  harmony  with  Anglican  teaching,  the  English 
church  had  received.10  As  an  ambassador,  he  approached  the  world 
of  commerce  from  the  standpoint  of  the  diplomatist ;  and  English 
diplomatists  have  generally,  from  that  day  to  this,  been  somewhat 
of  amateurs  in  financial  and  commercial  matters. 

The  moral  question  continued  to  be  much  discussed  by  many 

1 13  Elizabeth  c.  8  §  4;  cp.  Tawney,  op.  cit.  160-161.  2 Ibid  165-166. 

3  21  James  I.  c.  17 ;  reduced  to  six  per  cent  by  12  Charles  II.  c.  13.  Bacon  in  his 
essay  on  usury  had  advocated  a  reduction,  and  the  measure  was  approved  by  Malynes, 
Lex  Mercatoria  231-232. 

4  Op.  cit.  228. 

BFor  some  account  of  Wilson  see  Tawney's  edition  of  his  book,  1-15;  for  his 
speech  against  the  Act  see  ibid  159. 

6  The  Epistle  to  the  Earl  of  Leicester  prefixed  to  the  book  is  dated  July  25th,  1569, 
and  the  title  page  bears  the  date  1572 ;  cp.  Tawney,  op.  cit.  10. 

7  At  f.  73. 

8"  For  you  must  understande  that  usurie  is  oneley  geven  for  the  onely  benefitte  of 
lendynge  for  time.  Whereas  interest  is  demanded  when  I  have  susteyned  losse 
through  another  man's  cause,"  ibid  f.  133 ;  cp.  to  the  same  effect  Malynes,  op.  cit. 
228-229;  and  this  was  the  original  distinction  between  the  words — interest  is  "  that 
which  is  between  or  the  difference  between  the  creditor's  present  position  and  what  it 
would  have  been  had  the  bargain  been  fulfilled,"  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  399. 

9  Tawney,  op.  cit.  112-113,  116-117.  10  Vol.  i  594. 


USURY  AND  THE  USURY  LAWS      111 

English1  and  continental  writers  in  the  seventeenth  century.  - 
Some,  including  Malynes 3  and  Marquardus,4  advocated  the  retention 
of  the  mediaeval  idea,  that  in  considering  whether  any  given  bargain 
to  give  or  receive  interest  was  lawful,  regard  should  be  paid  to  the 
condition  of  the  borrower  and  the  purpose  of  the  loan.  It  would 
however  have  been  difficult  to  give  effect  to  this  principle  by 
direct  legislation,  and  no  attempt  was  made  to  give  effect  to  it  in 
this  way.  In  fact,  economic  theory  was  tending  to  the  view  that 
in  the  case  of  the  contract  of  loan,  as  in  other  cases,  persons  should 
be  free  to  make  what  bargains  they  pleased5 — "having  for  centuries," 
as  Mr.  Tawney  says,  "argued  with  little  reason  that  interest  was 
oppressive  in  all  circumstances,  within  half  a  century  of  Wilson's 
death  they  were  to  argue  with  even  less  reason  that  it  was  oppressive 
in  none." 6  But  in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries  the 
mediaeval  idea  was  to  some  extent  recognized  by  the  Council ; 7  and 
later  in  the  seventeenth  century  it  found  expression  in  the  growth 
of  the  equitable  control  over  bargains  with  persons  under  the 
pressure  of  necessity,  or  with  heirs,  reversioners,  or  others  entitled 
to  expectant  interests  in  property.8 

We  have  seen  that  §  4  of  the  Act  of  Elizabeth  was  not 
repeated  in  the  Act  of  James  I.  ;   and  the  later  debates  upon  this 

1  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  156-159. 

3  Ibid;  Ashley,  op.  cit.  i  Pt.  II.  453;  cp.  Marquardus,  De  Jure  Mercatorum  et 
Commerciorum  (ed.  1662)  ii  8,  32,  37,  46,  47,  53,  64 ;  iv  4,  8,  10-12. 

3  Op.  cit.  p.  243 — "  As  there  are  three  sorts  of  dealing  amongst  men,  that  is  Gift, 
Bargaining,  and  Lending ;  so  are  there  three  sorts  ot  men,  the  stark  beggar,  the  poor 
householder,  and  the  rich  merchant  or  gentleman.  To  the  first  you  ought  to  give  freely, 
not  only  to  lend  freely ;  to  the  second  you  ought  to  lend  either  freely  or  mercifully,  and 
not  to  feed  upon  him  with  excessive  usury :  but  with  the  third  you  may  deal  straightly, 
and  ask  your  own  with  gain  especially  when  he  gaineth  by  your  money  ;  using  in  all 
these  a  conscience  with  discretion." 

4  Op.  cit.  iv  4,  8, 10-12 — "  Usurarum  autem  prohibitarum  rursum  duo  sunt  genera ; 
unum  ex  parte  et  ratione  debitoris ;  alterius  respectu  creditoris.  Respectu  et  ratione 
debitoris  usurae  sunt  illicitae  et  prohibitae,  quarum  exactione  debitor  gravatur  et 
paulatim  quasi  consumitur :  hoc  est  quando  debitor  inops  et  pauper  factus  est,  non  ex 
delicto  suo  et  prodigalitate,  sed  fortunae  injuria.  ...  A  non  pauperibus  vero,  qui 
propter  indigentiam  suam  praesentem  non  inopiam,  sed  vel  lucrum  aliamve  instantem 
necessitatem  sumunt,  usurae  licitae  exiguntur.  .  .  .  Fieret  enim  alias  debitor  locupletior 
cum  creditoris  jactura.  Respectu  creditoris  illicitae  usurae  turn  sunt,  quando  debitor 
quidem  pauper  non  est,  sed  creditor  nihilominus  plus  justo  interesse  exigit,  nomine 
sortis  principalis  non  solutae." 

•Vol.  vi  356-360. 

8  Op.  cit.  60;  as  is  there  said,  doctrines  designed  to  protect  the  peasant  or  craftsman 
were  not  applicable  to  clothiers,  ironmasters,  and  other  capitalists  who  could  protect 
themselves;  a  modification  was  needed,  for  the  same  reason  as,  in  our  day,  a 
modification  of  the  equitable  doctrine  of  clogging  the  equity  of  redemption  was  needed. 

7  Thus  in  1600  one  Clarke  of  King's  Lynn  was  accused  of  extreme  and 
unconscionable  dealing  against  Bellingham  of  Peterborough ;  certain  persons  were 
appointed  to  reduce  Clarke  to  some  compromise,  and  to  make  him  restore  to 
Bellingham  his  copyhold  ;  if  he  will  not  do  so  they  were  to  certify  the  Council,  Dasent 
xxx  366 ;  cp.  Tawney,  op.  cit.  162-165. 

"The  leading  cases  are  Chesterfield  v.  Janssen  (1750)  1  Atk.  339;  Earl  of 
Aylesford  v.  Morris  (1873)  L.R.  8  Ch.  484 ;  on  the  whole  subject  see  Bellot,  Bargains 
with  Money  Lenders  Chap.  iv. 


112  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

question  show  how  rapidly  public  opinion  had  changed  since  I  571. 
"The  House  of  Commons  had  debated  anxiously,  if  unprofitably, 
under  Elizabeth  as  to  the  correct  interpretation  of  Scripture  :  in 
1 640  it  is  much  more  concerned  with  the  danger  of  driving  capital 
abroad."1  An  Act  of  Anne2  finally  reduced  the  rate  to  5  per 
cent ;  and  this  and  subsequent  Acts  excepted  certain  transactions 
from  the  operation  of  the  law.3  Subject  to  these  modifications 
and  exceptions,  the  scheme  of  the  Elizabethan  statute,  sup- 
plemented by  the  rules  of  equity,  was  the  basis  upon  which  the 
law  rested  down  to  the  repeal  of  the  usury  laws  in  1854,4  under 
the  influence  of  Bentham  and  the  economists.5  When,  in  1900, 
the  Legislature  saw  fit  to  resume  some  control  over  the  operations 
of  moneylenders,  it  directed  the  courts  to  apply  these  equitable 
doctrines  as  to  harsh  and  unconscionable  dealings,  when  they  were 
considering  the  question  whether  a  borrower  was  entitled  to 
relief.6  By  so  doing  it  has  again  brought  our  modern  law  into 
touch  with  the  policy  which  commended  itself  to  the  lawyers  and 
statesmen  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  and  with  the 
elements  of  substantial  truth  and  justice  which  underlay  the 
mediaeval  condemnation  of  usury. 

The  modification  of  the  mediaeval  prohibition  of  usury,  and 
the  consequent  growth  of  the  law  as  to  when  usury  was  permissible 
and  when  it  was  not,  show  us  that,  in  the  sixteenth  century,  the 
organization  of  commerce  and  industry  upon  a  capitalistic  basis 
was  an  established  fact.  This  new  organization  of  industry  was 
naturally  the  cause  of  great  changes  and  developments  in  com- 
mercial law — indeed,  it  is  the  ultimate  cause  of  the  shape  which  it 
has  assumed.  Two  of  its  most  important  consequences  were  the 
rise  and  growth  of  negotiable  instruments  and  the  institution  of 
banking.  At  the  present  day  negotiable  instruments  provide  for 
the  safety  of  capital,  by  affording  means  for  obviating  the  risks 
attendant  upon  the  physical  transport  or  exchange  of  the  precious 
metals ;  and  the  bank  provides,  in  the  first  place,  a  place  where 
capital  can  be  stored,  and,  in  the  second  place,  a  convenient  and 
safe  mechanism  by  which  this  stored  up  capital  can  be  used  as  and 
when  required.7     Both  in  this  way  bear  to  cash  payments  some- 

1  Tawney,  op.  cit.  171.  2  12  Anne  st.  2  c.  16. 

3  For  these  acts  see  Bellot,  op.  cit.  44,  45. 

4 17,  18  Victoria  c.  90.  5  Above  100-101. 

s  63,  64  Victoria  c.  51 — The  court  must  be  satisfied  (§  1.  1)  that  "  the  transaction 
is  harsh  and  unconscionable,  or  is  otherwise  such  that  a  court  of  equity  would  give 
relief." 

7  Thus  Marquardus,  De  jure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum,  ii  12.  33,  says  of  bills 
of  exchange,  "  in  summa  adeo  Reipublicae  necessaria  et  utilia  sunt  cambia,  ut,  si  ces- 
sarent,  omnia  fere  mercaturae  officia  destruerentur.  Et  sublata  negociationi  cambiorum 
e  medio  tolli  omnes  mercaturas  et  nundinas  "  ;   and  ibid  ii  14.  3,  he  says  of  payments 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         113 

what  the  same  historical  relation  that  cash  payments  bear  to  barter 
— they  mark  a  more  advanced  stage  of  commercial  organization. 
Both  also  began  to  assume  their  modern  forms  and  functions 
in  the  mediaeval  trading  centres  of  Southern  Europ :  and 
the  mediaeval  fairs  ;  and  both  during  this  period  spread  over 
Europe,  and  added  important  chapters  to  the  national  law  of  many 
states.  In  dealing  with  both  therefore  we  must  consider,  in  the 
first  place,  their  mediaeval  origins  and  continental  development, 
and,  in  the  second  place,  their  introduction  into  England  and  the 
manner  in  which  they  were  received  and  developed  by  the  com- 
mon law. 

But  though  from  many  points  of  view  we  can  rightly  regard 
these  institutions  as  connected  phenomena ;  though  each  has 
helped  forward  the  development  of  the  other  ;  yet  their  origins  are 
very  dissimilar  in  date  and  in  kind.  One  of  the  roots  of  the 
negotiable  instrument  must  be  sought  in  the  need  to  circumvent 
some  very  primitive  restrictions  found  in  many  bodies  of  archaic 
law ;  but  banks  and  banking  do  not  appear  till  commerce  and 
commercial  law  have  attained  a  relatively  high  degree  of  develop- 
ment. From  the  historical  point  of  view,  therefore,  they  must  be 
treated  separately.  I  shall  therefore  deal  with  them  separately  in 
the  two  succeeding  sections. 

§  2.  Negotiable  Instruments 

When  these  instruments  came  to  the  notice  of  the  English 
courts  in  the  sixteenth  century,  they  had  already  attained  a  de- 
velopment which  enables  us  to  see  in  germ  the  main  features  of 
the  negotiability  of  our  modern  law.  If,  therefore,  we  would 
understand  the  nature  of  these  instruments,  which  were  then 
introduced  to  English  lawyers,  we  must  first  examine  their 
mediaeval  origins  and  continental  development.  It  will  then  be 
possible  to  relate  the  history  of  their  introduction  into  England 
and  their  development  by  the  common  law. 

Medicev.zl  Origins  and  Continental  Development 

Before  I  begin  to  discuss  the  question  of  the  origins  of  these 
instruments,  it  will  perhaps  be  useful  to  concentrate  attention  upon 
the  object  of  our  search,  by  recalling  the  characteristic  features  of 
negotiability  in  our  modern  law.  They  are  three  in  number  :  (i) 
Negotiable  instruments  are  transferable  by  delivery  if  made  pay- 
able to  bearer,  or  by  indorsement  and  delivery  if  made  payable  to 

made  through  a  bank  that,  "  consuetudo  tamen  et  stylus  mercantilis  in  Italia  et  Ger- 
mania  viget,  ut  quaelibet  promissio,  facta  in  banco,  cedat  loco  solutionis." 
VOL.  VIII.— 8 


114  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

order  ;  and  the  transferee  to  whom  they  have  been  thus  delivered 
can  sue  upon  them  in  his  own  name,  (ii)  Consideration  is  pre- 
sumed, (iii)  A  transferee,  who  takes  one  of  these  instruments  in 
good  faith  and  for  value,  acquires  a  good  title,  even  though  his 
transferor  had  a  defective  title,  or  no  title  at  all.  Thus  the  ques- 
tions which  I  must  try  to  answer  are,  first,  what  were  the  germs 
from  which  instruments  having  these  qualities  were  developed ; 
and,  secondly,  what  were  the  technical  processes  by  which  this 
development  took  place? 

In  order  to  solve  these  questions  I  must  start  by  giving  some 
account  of  certain  documents,  in  which  a  person  places  himself 
under  a  liability  to  pay  or  perform  something,  either  (a)  to  the 
creditor  or  to  someone  else  nominated  by  the  creditor  and  pro- 
ducing the  document,  or  (b)  to  the  nominee  of  the  creditor  producing 
the  document,  or  (c)  to  the  creditor  or  the  producer  of  the  docu- 
ment, or  (d)  to  the  producer  of  the  document  simply.  These 
documents  come  from  a  very  early  period  in  the  history  of  law, 
and  were  not  necessarily  confined  to  mercantile  transactions. 
But,  with  the  development  of  commerce,  they  necessarily  came  to 
be  used  most  frequently  in  these  transactions.  However,  in  the 
sixteenth  century,  their  commercial  usefulness  was  almost  entirely 
destroyed,  because  the  lawyers,  under  the  influence  of  the  technical 
conceptions  of  the  civil  law,  so  construed  them  that  they  lost  the 
negotiable  characteristics  which  they  had  formerly  possessed.  The 
merchants  were  therefore  obliged  to  evolve  some  other  expedient. 
This  expedient  was  found  in  the  adaptation  of  another  kind  of 
instrument  which,  in  the  late  thirteenth  and  early  fourteenth  cen- 
turies, had  been  invented  for  the  purpose  of  effecting  an  exchange 
of  money  without  incurring  the  risks  of  its  physical  transportation. 
This  instrument  was  the  Bill  of  Exchange.  This  new  and 
essentially  commercial  document  gradually  attracted  to  itself  some 
of  the  qualities  which  these  older  documents  had  originally  pos- 
sessed ;  and,  as  it  was  in  connection  with  these  bills  of  exchange 
that  the  characteristic  features  of  the  negotiability  of  our  modern 
law  obtained  their  final  form  and  recognition,  they  naturally  came 
to  be  regarded  as  the  type  and  model  of  the  negotiable  instru- 
ment. Naturally  this  development  led  to  a  revival  of  the 
negotiable  qualities  of  some  of  those  older  instruments  which  had 
lost  their  negotiable  characteristics  in  the  course  of  the  sixteenth 
century. 

I  shall  therefore  group  my  account  of  these  developments  under 
the  two  following  heads :  firstly,  the  early  documents  authorizing 
the  debtor  to  pay  the  creditor  or  his  nominee,  or  the  creditor  or 
the  producer  of  the  document ;  and,  secondly,  the  origin  and  develop- 
ment of  the  bill  of  exchange. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         115 

( I )  The  early  documents  authorizing  the  debtor  to  pay  the  creditor 
or  his  nominee,  or  the  creditor  or  the  producer  of  the  document. 

Even  in  modern  times  the  legal  consequences  of  negotiability 
are  exceptions  to  the  ordinary  rules  of  law.  In  ancient  law  any- 
thing approaching  a  negotiable  instrument  was  legally  impossible, 
for  three  reasons.  Firstly,  ancient  systems  of  law  do  not  allow  one 
man  to  represent  another  in  litigation  before  a  tribunal.  When 
this  prohibition  began  to  be  relaxed,  representation  was  at  first  an 
exceptional  privilege,  and  the  representative  must  be  formally  and 
solemnly  appointed.1  Secondly,  ancient  systems  of  law  do  not 
allow  a  creditor  to  assign  his  right  to  another.2  That  the  relation 
of  debtor  and  creditor  was  a  strictly  personal  relation  is  obvious 
from  the  strictly  personal  character  of  the  creditor's  remedy — he 
could  even  imprison  the  debtor.  Therefore  it  was  only  just  that 
the  creditor  and  the  creditor  alone  should  be  able  to  enforce  his 
claim.3  Thirdly,  such  a  transfer,  even  if  otherwise  permissible, 
was  impossible,  because  there  could  be  no  transfer  of  anything 
without  a  physical  delivery  of  possession ;  and  how  can  the  right 
to  enforce  the  payment  of  a  debt  be  physically  transferred  ?  4 

In  Northern  Italy  many  of  these  difficulties  were  circumvented 
by  the  Lombard  lawyers  of  the  eighth  and  ninth  centuries.  They 
resorted  to  two  different  sets  of  expedients.  In  the  first  place,  they 
drew  up  documents  in  which  the  person  liable  promises  perform- 
ance not  only  to  a  specified  creditor,  but  also  to  any  one  who 
produces  the  document  as  the  creditor's  nominee.5  Thus  in  771  a 
monk  made  over  to  a  church  the  right  to  avenge  his  death  if  he 

1  Brunner,  Les  Titres  au  porteur  francais  du  moyen  age,  N.R.H.,  x  12-16 ;  cp. 
vol.  ii  315-317 ;  Professor  Wigmore  has  pointed  out  to  me  that  Brunner's  conclusions 
have  been  combated  in  an  essay  by  Brandileone,  published  in  1903  by  J.  Vallardi,  Milan, 
which  is  a  reprint  from  vol.  i  of  Rivista  di  diritto  commerciale  e  maritimo  ;  but  that 
Brunner's  views  have  been  vindicated  in  a  later  essay  by  Mario  Palazzo,  La  question 
dell'  origine  del  titolo  a  portatore  (1905,  Torino,  Tipografia  Salesiana,  Via  Cottolango, 
32)  at  pp.  54,  87,  115. 

2  Brunner,  op.  cit.  16-19;  V<>1.  vii  518,  520-521;  for  the  manner  in  which  the 
influence  of  the  civil  and  canon  law  made  for  a  modification  of  this  rule,  see  below 
"7.  !23- 

3 "  Pas  plus  qu'on  ne  s'explique  aujourd'hui  un  changement  du  d£biteur  sans 
l'assentiment  du  creancier,  pas  plus  on  n'aurait  compris  autrefois  la  substitution  d'un 
creancier  a  un  autre.  Cela  tenait  encore  a  ce  que  les  durs  moyens  de  coercition  dont 
les  cr£anciers  etaient  armes,  la  contrainte  par  corps,  par  exemple,  pouvaient  etre 
manias  de  facon  tres  diverse,  suivant  l'humeur  des  personnes  qui  avaient  a  les  faire 
valoir,"  Brissaud,  Hist  du  droit  francais,  ii  1434  ;  as  Marquardus,  De  Jure  Mercatorum 
et  Commerciorum,  says  (ii  7,  10)  speaking  of  later  law:  "Nee  enim  creditoris  petitio 
ipso  invito  immutari  aut  ipsi  alius  debitor  obtrudi,  licet  debitoris  actio  et  chirographum 
a  creditore  invito  debitore  alii  cedi  possit,  cum  ejus  non  intersit  cui  solvat" 

*  Vol.  iii  92  n.  10;  vol.  vii  518 ;  cp.  Jenks,  Essays,  A.A.L.H.,  iii  65,  66. 

5  Brunner,  op.  cit,,  31 ;  Jenks,  op.  cit,  61,  62  ;  many  examples  can  be  found  in 
the  Codex  Cavensis,  a  collection  of  deeds  from  the  archives  of  the  Cluniac  monastery 
at  La  Cava  near  Salerno,  and  now  published  (see  Jenks,  op.  cit.  60,  61) ;  the  other 
collection  which  illustrates  this  expedient  will  be  found  in  vol.  v  of  Memorie  e  Documenti 
per  servire  all'  istoria  del  Ducato  de  Lucca ;  it  contains  a  reprint  of  the  cathedral  docu- 
ments from  the  seventh  to  the  tenth  centuries  (Jenks,  loc.  cit.). 


116  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

should  be  murdered,  and  the  right  was  to  be  enforced,  "per  se  vel 
per  ilium  hominem  cui  ipse  hanc  cartulam  dederit  ad  exigendum."  * 
Similarly  it  was  provided  that  a  performance  should  be  made  to  a 
creditor,  "vel  cui  istum  breve  in  manu  paruerit  in  vice  nostra."  2 
In  the  second  place,  they  drew  up  documents  in  which  the  person 
liable  promises  performance,  sometimes  to  the  creditor  or  the  pro- 
ducer of  the  document,  sometimes  to  the  producer  of  the  document 
simply.3  Thus,  in  the  middle  of  the  ninth  century,  a  person 
promised,  "tibi  aut  eidem  homini  qui  hunc  scriptum  pro  manibus 
abuerit,"4  or  "mihi  seu  ad  hominem  ilium  apud  quern  brebem 
iste  in  manu  paruerit "  ; 5  and  in  the  middle  of  the  tenth  century  a 
person  promised,  "  ad  hominem  apud  quern  iste  scriptus  paruerit."  G 

It  should  be  noted  that  these  clauses  are  to  be  found  in  many 
various  kinds  of  documents.  They  are  to  be  found  in  wills  and 
conveyances  as  well  as  in  documents  which  acknowledge  indebted- 
ness. Thus  an  example  of  the  year  1036  is  thus  described  by 
Professor  Jenks : 7  "A  certain  'comes  Petrus '  by  his  will  left  the 
guardianship  of  his  wife  and  all  belonging  thereto  to  h\s  germani 
Malfred  and  John,  or  illi  vivo  cui  scriptum  in  manu  paruerit.  Thirty 
years  later,  a  certain  clerk  John  appeared  in  court  as  guardian  of 
the  widow,  and  was  accepted  as  such  without  a  question  on  pro- 
duction of  the  document. "  But  it  is  clear  that  they  could  be  used 
in  documents  which  acknowledged  that  the  debtor  owed  money  to 
a  creditor,  just  as  easily  as  in  documents  in  which  a  testator  or  a 
settlor  conveys  benefits  to  a  named  person.  And  that  documents 
of  this  kind  spread  over  Europe  in  the  thirteenth  century  there  is 
much  evidence.  Brunner  has  shown  that  both  varieties  were  well 
known  in  France  in  this  and  the  following  centuries.8  In  England 
they  were  known  to  Brae  ton  under  the  name  of  missibilia}  In 
the  fair  courts  we  meet  with  scripta  obligatoria,  which  could  be 
enforced  sometimes  by  the  certain  attorney  or  the  nuncius  of  the 
creditor,  sometimes  by  the  producer  of  the  document.10  In  the 
Mayor's  Court  in  London  in  1 304-1 305  an  action  of  detinue  was 
brought  for  two  bills  of  £yo  15s.  nd.,  "which  the  plaintiff  had 
bought  from  William  Foundepe,  merchant."11 

The  effect  given  to  these  clauses  helped  to  get  over  the  three 
difficulties  which  prevented  the  recognition  of  anything  like  a 
negotiable  instrument. 

1.  If  a  debtor  had  promised  to  pay  the  creditor  or  his  attorney 
or  nuncius,  many  of  the  difficulties  attaching  to  the  representation 

I  Jenks,  op.  cit.  61.  2  Ibid  61,  62.  3  Ibid  62  4  Ibid. 
5  Ibid.                                       "  Ibid.                             7  Ibid  63,  64. 

8  Brunner,  op.  cit.  32-36  (examples  of  clauses  to  bearer) ;  ibid  162-169  (examples 
of  clauses  to  order) ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1438. 

9  At  f.  41b ;  P.  and  M.  ii  225.  10  Vol.  i  543  ;  vol.  v  114. 

II  Thomas,  Calendar  of  early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  172. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT        117 

of  a  litigant  before  a  tribunal  disappeared.  It  is  true  that  the  title 
of  the  plaintiff  to  be  the  representative  of  the  principal  must  be 
proved.  It  is  true  also  that  in  these  early  days  he  must  be  formally 
appointed  like  any  other  representative.  But  the  fact  that  the 
debtor  had  bound  himself  to  pay  to  the  creditor  or  his  nominee 
prevented  him  from  raising  any  objection  to  the  appointment1  In 
these  cases,  however,  it  is  clear  that  the  instrument  can  hardly  be 
said  to  have  had  anything  like  a  negotiable  character.  The  nominee 
sued  as  the  creditor's  agent.  Defences  good  against  the  principal 
were  good  against  him.-  The  death  of  the  principal  put  an  end 
to  his  authority  ; 3  and  the  representative  could  not  delegate  his 
powers  to  another  representative.4  Probably  the  rights  of  the 
nominee  were  larger,  he  had  a  more  independent  position  of  his 
own,  if  the  debtor  had  promised  to  pay  any  one  nominated  by  the 
creditor,  and  the  nominee  sued,  not  as  agent,  but  in  his  own  name. 
As  the  debtor  could  not  question  his  authority  or  his  title  to  the 
instrument  on  which  he  sued,  an  instrument  with  the  clause  per- 
mitting the  nominee  to  sue  in  his  own  name  probably  did  possess 
certain  negotiable  characteristics.5  At  any  rate,  we  shall  see  that 
this  was  the  case  in  the  thirteenth  and  fourteenth  centuries.''  But 
it  was  the  instruments  enforceable  by  the  creditor  or  the  producer, 
or  by  the  producer  simply,  which  possessed  these  negotiable 
characteristics  in  a  far  higher  degree. 

2.  Instruments  containing  this  clause  got  over  the  difficulty 
that  a  debt  could  not  be  assigned,  and  sometimes  put  the  assignee 
in  a  better  position  than  his  assignor.  If  a  debtor  had  promised 
to  pay  to  the  creditor  or  the  producer  of  the  instrument,  or  to  the 
producer  simply,  the  producer  could  sue  in  his  own  right  as  if  he 
were  the  creditor."  He  was  the  "  dominus  litis,"  or  the  "seigneur 
de  la  chose,"  8  as  a  French  custumal  calls  him.  The  death  of  the 
original  creditor  did  not  affect  his  right  to  sue.9     He  need  not  show 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit.  169,  clearly  explains  the  advantages  of  this  ;  when  the  right  to 
represent  another  was  restricted,  the  consent  of  the  defendant  to  be  sued  by  the  plaintiff's 
representative  would  get  over  the  difficulty :  "  seulement  ce  consentement  etait 
probablement  tres  difficile  a  obtenir,  lorsqu'il  n'etait  demande  que  dans  le  but  de  com- 
mencer  le  proces,  car  le  defendeur  avait  tout  interet  a  ne  pas  faciliter  la  procedure  au 
demandeur.  Mais  si  le  crgancier  s'etait  assure  d'avance  le  consentement  du  debiteur 
dans  le  contrat  meme,  si  le  debiteur  s'etait  oblige  par  la  reconnaissance  de  payer  even- 
tuellement  au  mandataire  ou  procureur  du  creancier,  le  debiteur  poursuivi  en  justice  ne 
pouvait  pas  s'opposer  a  l'admission  du  representant  du  demandeur." 

-  Ibid  170.  3  Ibid  op.  cit.  iS ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1438  n.  5. 

*  Brunner,  op.  cit.  174. 

5  Ibid  169,  179  ;  cp.  Debray,  These,  De  la  clause  a  ordre  [1892]  30-32 — in  some 
of  the  French  provinces  he  was  allowed  to  sue  on  his  own  account,  though  a  stranger 
to  the  original  contract ;  Debray,  op.  cit.  31-32,  points  out  that  as  late  as  1437  the 
custumal  of  Anjou  and  Maine  stated  that  "  Ne  aucun  ne  peut  recevoir  convenance  pour 
autre  si  ce  n'est  pour  son  proufitt  ou  si  ce  ti'est  dc  son  commandement.'" 

6  Below  120  ;  last  note. 

7  Brunner,  op.  cit.  39,  40,  citing  Bouteiller,  Somme  Rurale. 

8  Ibid.  »  Ibid  41. 


118  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

how  he  came  by  the  document.1  Defences  available  against  the 
original  debtor  were  probably  not  available  against  him.2  He 
was  in  a  sense  a  party  to  the  contract  because  he  is  the  producer 
of  the  instrument,  and  it  was  the  producer  that  the  debtor  had 
contracted  to  pay.  When  he  sues  upon  the  instrument  he  is  there- 
fore asserting  a  right  of  his  own,3  and  can  sue  either  personally  or 
by  agent.4  It  follows  that  these  instruments,  and  the  rights  con- 
ferred by  them,  could  freely  circulate  from  hand  to  hand. 

3.  The  third  difficulty  in  the  way  of  transferring  a  right  to 
receive  a  debt — the  difficulty  that  there  can  be  no  transfer  without 
the  physical  delivery  of  some  res — was  removed  by  the  growth  of 
the  idea  that  there  can  be  a  symbolical  transfer,  by  the  delivery  of 
the  charter  which  witnesses  the  transfer.5  The  Anglo-Saxon  land 
book  may  have  been  used,  not  merely  as  the  evidence  of  a  con- 
veyance, but  as  the  conveyance  itself; 6  and  though  in  later  times 
the  royal  courts  in  England  refused  to  allow  this  efficacy  to  a  deed, 
abroad  this  method  of  conveyance  was  well  recognized.7  It  was 
certainly  so  recognized  in  Lombard  law,8  and  the  influence  of 
Roman  law  made  for  its  extension.9  Now  it  is  clear  that  this 
conception  is  capable  of  development ;  and  it  is  the  more  possible 
to  develop  it  in  primitive  systems  of  law,  in  which  the  lines  between 
property  and  obligation,  between  conveyance  and  contract,  are  by 
no  means  clearly  drawn.  In  this  primitive  period  the  charter 
which  made  a  contract  was  regarded  as  the  contract  itself;  and  its 
traditio  clinched  the  bargain.10  Therefore  any  one  into  whose  hands 
this  charter  came  could  present  it  to  the  debtor  and  demand  its 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit.  43,  44,  148. 

2  Ibid  41,  45,  151,  152;  on  this  point  Bouteiller  is  silent;  Brunner  says  that  he 
could  not  be  met  by  the  plea  of  set-off,  as  this  plea  was  excluded  in  all  personal  actions, 
and  only  permitted  to  a  debtor  as  a  special  privilege  given  by  the  king ;  and  at  pp. 
151,  152,  probably  not  by  any  defence  if  he  had  taken  in  good  faith. 

3"  Puisque  le  porteur  d'icelle  a  encommance"  la  cause  et  petition  des  dictes  lettres 
en  court,  il  est  fait  seigneur  de  la  poursuyte  et  action  d'icelles  entierement,  et  en  peut 
faire  comme  il  luy  plaist,  perdre  ou  gaigner  en  jugement,  si  comme  pure  ct  principale 
partie,  ct  faire  quittance  ou  don,  comme  bon  luy  semble,"  Bouteiller,  Somme  Rurale, 
f.  151,  cited  Brunner,  op.  cit.  40;  as  Brunner  says  (ibid  47) :  "  A  l'egard  du  debiteur 
le  porteur  est  regarde  comme  creancier  ;  c'est  lui  qui  intente  Taction  et  conclut  a  la 
condamnation  du  debiteur  aux  depens." 

4  Ibid  40;  of  course,  he  cannot  transfer  after  proceedings  have  been  begun,  ibid. 

6  Vol.  iii  222-223  ;  "  La  charte  est  placed  souvent  sur  la  meme  ligne  que  la  festuca 
ou  le  wadium,  sans  doute  parce  qu'elle  a  la  meme  efncacite'  :  on  fait  tradition  par  le 
rameau  ou  par  la  charte,"  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1395  n.  3. 

6  Vol.  ii  77  ;  vol.  iii  223.  7  Ibid  223-225. 

8  Jenks,  op.  cit.  65. 

9  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1284,  1302- 1305. 

10  "  On  s'oblige  per  cartam  comme  par  la  festuca  ou  le  wadium,  et,  l'influence  ger- 
manique  agissant,  ce  n'est  pas  seulement  la  redaction  de  l'acte  qui  est  prise  en  con- 
sideration, c'est  sa  remise  mat6rielle  au  cr^ancier.  .  .  .  L'ignorance  et  la  defiance 
.  .  .  ne  durent  pas  peu  contribuer  a  rapprocher  la  carta  des  symboles  mat£riels  en 
usage  pour  le  transfert  de  la  propriety  et  la  formation  des  contrats,"  Brissaud,  op.  cit. 
ii  1395- 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         119 

enforcement,  if  the  charter  had  so  provided.1  Thus,  by  means  of 
these  charters,  in  which  the  debtor  had  promised  to  pay  the  creditor 
or  producer,  or  the  producer  simply,  the  property  in  a  debt  could 
be  transferred  with  the  writing  from  hand  to  hand. 

In  these  ancient  documents,  therefore,  we  can  see  that  methods 
had  been  devised  for  breaking  down  the  archaic  formalism  of 
primitive  law,  which  would  otherwise  have  prevented  the  growth 
of  anything  like  a  negotiable  instrument  But  as  yet  these  methods 
were  crude  and  unformed.  They  must  be  developed  by  legal 
theory  and  commercial  practice  before  the  negotiable  instruments 
of  our  modern  law  could  be  evolved  from  them.  And  legal  theory, 
for  a  time,  was  hostile  to  their  development.  In  many  different 
places,  and  at  many  different  times,  the  lawyers  have  been  slow  to 
learn  that  their  technical  rules  must,  in  the  long  run,  accommodate 
themselves  to  business  needs — that  commercial  law  exists  primarily 
to  settle  mercantile  disputes,  and  not  to  dictate  to  the  merchants 
the  modes  in  which  they  shall  carry  on  their  business.  These  in- 
struments were  absolutely  necessary  to  commerce ;  and  it  was 
therefore  inevitable  that  legal  technicalities  should,  in  the  long  run, 
yield  to  mercantile  necessities.  But  the  marks  of  the  conflict  can 
be  plainly  read  in  the  law  which  resulted  ;  and  it  is,  therefore,  not 
till  this  conflict  has  been  fought  out  and  decided,  that  the  modern 
incidents  of  the  negotiable  instrument  appear.  The  first  stages  of 
this  conflict  can  be  read  in  the  history  of  the  development  of  these 
clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor's  nominee,  or  of  the  producer  of  the 
document,  which  we  have  just  been  discussing. 

The  clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor* 's  nominee. — We  find  in  the 
Middle  Ages  many  varieties  of  these  clauses.  They  fall  into  two 
main  classes,  (i)  There  is  the  class  in  which  the  representative 
character  of  the  nominee  is  not  prominent,  and  (ii)  there  is  the 
class  in  which  it  is  clearly  emphasized.2  And  in  both  classes  the 
clause  is  sometimes  alternative,  i.e.  the  promise  is  to  pay  to  the 
creditor  or  his  nominee;  and  sometimes  simple,  i.e.  the  promise  is 
to  pay  to  the  nominee.3 

(i)  Instances  of  clauses  of  the  first  class  are  promises  to  pay  to 
you,  the  creditor,  vel  cui  mandaveris  ;  or  to  pay  mandato  tuo,  or 
tibi  vel  mandato  tuo,  or  tibi  vel  certo  mandato  ;  or  to  pay  to  X  or 
a  son  command,  son  certein  command,  son  commandement ,  or 
mandement ;  or  to  pay  to  X  on  a  son  command  ces  lettres  portant ; 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit.  150,  151,  compares  his  position  with  that  of  the  Salman  :  "  Le 
porteur,  simple  mandataire,  est  regards  comme  crdancier,  le  salmann,  egalement 
simple  mandataire,  est  regards  comme  proprietaire.  .  .  .  Le  poiteur,  de  memeque  le 
salmann,  n'agit  pas,  en  ce  qui  concerne  la  forme,  comme  fonde  de  pouvoir  du 
mandant,  mais  en  vertu  de  son  propre  droit,  le  porteur  comme  creancier  fiduciaire,  le 
salmann  comme  proprietaire  fiduciaire  "  ;  for  the  Salman  see  vol.  iii  563-564  ;  vol.  iv. 
410-412. 

3  Brunner,  op.  cit.,  169,  170.  3  Ibid  162-169. 


120  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

or  to  pay  ei  quern  tnihi  ordinaveris}  It  was  this  last  formula — to 
pay  to  the  order  of — which  was  destined,  as  we  shall  see,  to 
supersede  the  others.2 

(ii)  Instances  of  clauses  of  the  second  class  are  promises  to  pay 
to  X  vel  procuratori  suo,  ou  a  leur  procureur  pour  eulx  et  en  leur 
nomt  suo  attornato,  certo  nuncio  suo;  or  to  pay  nuncio  or  attovnato 
litteras  deferenti,  or  a  son  certain  message  qui  ces  lettres  apportera? 

It  is  probable  that  in  the  thirteenth  and  fourteenth  centuries 
the  legal  effects  of  these  two  classes  of  clauses  were  very  different. 
A  nominee  who  sued  in  his  own  name  on  a  document  which  con- 
tained a  clause  of  the  first  class,  could  rely  on  the  promise  of  the 
debtor  to  pay  such  a  nominee.  He  need  not  prove  any  causa  for 
the  transfer  to  himself.  He  need  not  prove  his  title  to  sue  as 
agent,  or  his  title  to  the  instrument,  for  he  is  in  effect  suing  as 
creditor  under  the  instrument.  On  the  other  hand,  a  nominee  who 
sued  in  his  creditor's  name  on  a  document  which  contained  a  clause 
of  the  first  class,  or  a  nominee  who  sued  as  agent  on  a  document 
which  contained  a  clause  of  the  second  class,  was  treated  strictly  as 
an  agent.  He  must  prove  his  authority,  and  all  defences  good 
against  the  principal  were  good  against  him.4  Whichever  clause 
was  used,  the  nominee  could  not  transfer  his  rights  to  another. 
In  this  respect  it  differed  entirely  from  the  document  made  pay- 
able to  the  producer,  which  could  pass  from  hand  to  hand  to  an 
unlimited  extent.5 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit.  162-166. 

2  The  clause  "  vel  cui  ordinaverit  M  is  found  in  a  Genoese  document  of  May  18, 
1160  :  "  Nos  Bonusiohannes  Tinea  et  Adalasia  jugales  accepimus  a  te  Wilhelmo 
Burone  libras  X  den.  januens,  quas  tibi  vel  tuo  misso  per  nos  vel  nostrum  missum 
dabimus  ...  si  non  in  Sicilia  dabimus  nuncio  tuo  Jonathe  Cerriolo  ant  ci  quern  tnihi 
ordinaveris  uncias  auri  vi,"  Mon.  patriae  Chart.  II.,  no.  882,  col.  650,  cited  N.R.H. 
x  165  ;  as  Brunner  says  (ibid  165,  166),  the  clause  to  order  became  the  usual 
clause  in  bills  of  exchange  in  the  seventeenth  century,  and  ' '  Comme  en  France,  la 
formule  '  a  l'ordre,'  qui  vient  d'ltalie  et  qui  est  maintenant  devenue  internationale,  a 
aussi  supplants  presque  completement  en  Allemagne  les  anciennes  clauses  a  ordre 
nationales,  parmi  lesquelles  la  formule,  '  oder  an  den  getreuen  Inhaber  (ou  au  fidele 
porteur),'  avait  £te"  la  plus  usitee  dans  les  derniers  temps." 

3  Brunner,  op.  cit.  167,  168. 

4  "  Le  command  et  le  procureur  different  en  ce  point  que  le  premier  avait  une 
plus  grande  liberte  d'agir.  Le  command  peut  plaider  en  son  nom  propre  .  .  .  il 
peut  fonder  son  action  sur'le  fait  qui  sert  de  cause  a  la  tradition  de  la  lettre.  Mais 
la  cause  peut  aussi  rester  occulte  vis-a-vis  des  tiers,  car  le  d^biteur  a  promis  de  payer 
a  la  personne  denomm£e  ou  a  celui  '  cui  mandavcrit.'1  Le  command  peut  done 
invoquer  le  seul  ordre  du  principal  de  payer  au  command,  sans  indiquer  la  cause 
de  la  tradition.  Quand  le  command  agit  en  ce  sens,  la  difference  qui  existe,  pour 
le  fond,  entre  le  representant  et  le  crdancier,  disparait  dans  le  procrs.  .  .  .  Le  pro- 
cureur n'est  pas  aussi  libre  que  le  command  dans  la  maniere  de  fonder  son  action. 
La  teneur  meme  de  la  clause  de  procuration  l'oblige  d'intenter  Taction  au  nom  du 
principal  et  d'invoquer  la  procuration  que  le  principal  lui  a  donnee  a  l'effet  de  se 
i'aire  representor  en  justice.  .  .  .  Les  exceptions  n£es  de  faits  personnels  au  principal 
peuvent  etre  oppos^es  au  representant,"  ibid  169,  170. 

5  "  Le  titre  pourvu  de  la  clause  a  ordre  n'admettait  qu'une  seule  transmission,  car 
le  command  dtait  oblig^  de  prouver  que  le  titre  lui  avait  etc  remis  par  la  personne 
d^nommce,     Ordinairement  il  etablissait  cette  preuve  par  un  mandatum  ecrit  de  la 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         121 

These  clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor's  nominee  had  become 
rare  in  the  fifteenth  century ;  and  in  the  sixteenth  century  they 
had  disappeared.1  In  the  first  place,  the  lawyers,  under  the  in- 
fluence of  the  technical  conceptions  of  the  civil  law,  ignored  the 
older  difference  between  these  two  classes  of  clauses,  and  laid  it 
down  that  the  creditor's  nominee  could  sue  only  in  the  capacity  of 
the  creditor's  agent2  In  the  second  place,  the  greater  convenience 
of  the  clauses  enabling  the  producer  of  the  document  to  sue 
caused  them  to  supersede  these  clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor's 
nominee.3  It  was  not  till  the  seventeenth  century  that  these 
clauses  reappear,  in  the  form  of  the  clause  to  order  of  our  modern 
law,  in  connection  with  an  entirely  different  class  of  instrument.4 
But  in  order  to  understand  the  reasons  for  this  new  development 
we  must  know  something  of  the  history  of  the  clauses  in  favour  of 
the  producer  of  these  documents. 

The  clauses  in  favour  of  the  producer  of  the  document. — Just  as 
from  the  clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor's  nominee  the  clause  to 
order  of  our  modern  law  is  ultimately  derived,  so  from  these  clauses 
in  favour  of  the  producer  of  the  document  springs  our  modern 
clause  to  bearer.  The  position  of  the  producer  of  one  of  these 
documents,  in  the  thirteenth  and  fourteenth  centuries,  almost 
exactly  corresponds  to  the  position  of  the  bearer  of  a  negotiable 
instrument.  I  shall,  therefore,  for  the  future  speak  of  him  under 
his  modern  name  of  bearer. 

We  have  seen  that  the  bearer  was  allowed  to  sue  upon  the 
contract  in  his  own  right,  because  the  debtor  had  contracted  to 
pay  the  creditor  or  the  bearer  of  the  document,  or  the  bearer  of  the 
document  simply.0  This  was  his  position  in  France,  and  probably 
in  other  countries  also,  till  the  end  of  the  fourteenth  century.6 
But,  at  the  end  of  the  fourteenth  century,  we  can  see  that  the  same 
body  of  doctrine  which  had  destroyed  the  independent  position  of 
nominee  of  the  creditor  is  beginning  to  affect  the  position  of  the 
bearer.  As  with  the  creditor's  nominee  so  with  the  bearer,  the 
lawyers  were  beginning  to  reduce  him  to  the  position  of  the  agent 
of  the  creditor." 

This  change  in  the  position  of  the  bearer  is  due,  as  Brunner 

personne  denommee.  Le  titre  a  ordre  ancien  se  distinguait,  a  cet  egard,  essentielle 
ment  du  titre  au  porteur,  qui  pouvait  circuler  par  plusieurs  mains,"  Brunner, 
op,  cit.  174. 

1  Debray,  op.  cit.  35-37,  "  Au  xvie  siecle  elle  a  disparu  ;  toutes  les  formules  qui 
la  contenaient  l'ont  remplacee  par  la  clause  au  porteur  ;  la  comparaison  entre  la 
Summe  artis  notaria  et  le  Stile  des  notaires  est  saisissante  a  ce  point  de  vue." 

2"Onn'y  vit  plus  qu'un  mandat,"  ibid  36.  The  form  of  the  clause — *'  vel  cui 
mandaveris  " — helped  this  development. 

3  Ibid  35.  4  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1440. 

"Above  117-11S.  6  Cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1438  n.  1. 

7  The  history  of  this  process  in  France  is  worked  out  in  great  detail  by  Brunner, 
op.  cit.  139-147, 


122  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

has  pointed  out,1  to  the  fundamental  difference  existing  between 
the  Germanic  and  the  Roman  procedure.  As  he  says,  "  The 
Germanic  procedure  does  not  ask,  What  is  the  right  of  the  plain- 
tiff? Its  point  of  view  is  the  duty  of  defence,  and  the  means  of 
defence  open  to  the  defendant.  The  main  question  in  these 
personal  actions  is  the  question  whether  the  defendant  is  or  is  not 
bound  to  pay ;  and  his  obligation  to  pay  the  bearer  is  the  direct 
consequence  of  the  form  of  his  promise  to  pay."  But  in  the 
procedure  of  the  civil  and  canon  law  the  point  of  view  is  the  right 
of  the  plaintiff.  The  assertion  of  that  right  is  the  object  of  the 
action.  Thus,  "  this  system,  in  which  the  first  question  is  always, 
Has  the  plaintiff  a  right  of  action?  made  it  necessary  for  the 
French  lawyers  to  find  some  explanation  of  the  bearer's  right  of 
action.  They  found  it  necessary  to  discover  some  legal  basis  on 
which  they  could  rest  it."  Probably  this  difficulty  was  especially 
keenly  felt  by  the  French  lawyers,  because  the  Renaissance  school 
of  jurists,  which  was  especially  influential  in  France,  endeavoured 
to  get  back  as  far  as  possible  to  the  classical  texts.2  They  there- 
fore rejected  many  of  those  modifications  of  pure  classical  doctrine, 
which  the  influence  of  the  older  customary  law,  and  commercial 
convenience  and  practice,  had  caused  the  school  of  the  glossators 
to  accept.  But  the  difficulty  was  not  confined  to  the  French 
lawyers.  It  was  felt  in  Italy,  and  indeed  in  all  countries  in  which 
Roman  law  was  received,  in  proportion  to  the  extent  to  which  the 
doctrines  of  that  law  gained  supremacy.3  The  lawyers  were  at 
once  learned  in  the  classical  texts  of  Justinian's  Corpus  Juris,  and 
ignorant  of  the  modern  mechanism  of  commerce.  They  did  not 
hesitate,  therefore,  to  sacrifice  commercial  convenience  on  the 
shrine  of  legal  orthodoxy — even  suggesting  that  the  merchants 
purposely  adopted  obscure  forms  in  order  that  illegal  transactions 
might  pass  unnoticed.4  On  the  other  hand,  the  technical  difficulty 
was  not  felt  so  keenly  in  Northern  Europe,5  nor,  as  we  shall  see, 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit.  154,  155.  2  Vol.  iv  225-228. 

3  Below  123  nn.  3  and  5. 

4  Scaccia,  Tractatus  de  commerciis  et  cambio  (§  1  Quaest.  ii  16),  explaining  the 
difficulty  of  this  branch  of  the  law,  says  that  difficulties  arise  "  Propter  concisos  et 
nostris  jurisconsultis  incognitos  terminos  quibus  negotiatio  haec  brevissimis  conficitur 
litteris,  adeo  quod  materiam  istam  cambii  esse  in  se  difficilem  intellectu  .  .  .  et  esse 
difficilem  propter  extraneos  terminos  quibus  mercatores  utuntur  .  .  .  imo  posset  quis 
probabiliter  dubitare,  cambiorum  negotiatores  de  industria  hunc  concissum  abstrusum 
et  perplexum  loquendi,  contrahendique  modum  excogitare,  ut  jurisconsult'',  aliique 
docti  viri,  ignoratis  cambiorum  ter minis,  ea  damnare  nesciant." 

6  Thus  Marquardus.  De  jure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum  (ed.  1662)  ii  14.  o, 
says  :  "  Notandum  et  hie  per  clausulam  vulgatam,  Eive  qui  hanc  fert,  ex  more  inter 
mercatores  frequentissimo  syngraphis  inseri  solitam,  latori  non  solum  adjecto 
recte,  solvi,  sed  et  actionem  ei  a  creditore  mandatam  cessamque  praesumi  .  .  .  imo 
nee  eum  titulum  ostendere  nee  bonam  fidem  probari  necesse  habere  "  ;  cp.  ibid  ii 
7.  8-10,  where  he  explains  that  an  unlimited  number  of  indorsements  may  be 
made ;    "  Delegans  mercator  et  creditor  Dantiscanus  per  cambii   solutionem   tertio 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         123 

in  England.  It  is  probable  that  in  these  places  the  older  ideas 
lived  on,  and  saved  the  lawyers  the  trouble  of  finding  a  new 
speculative  basis,  consonant  with  the  doctrines  of  Roman  law,  upon 
which  the  peculiar  characteristics  of  negotiable  instruments  could 
be  based. 

The  difficulties  felt  by  the  lawyers  of  the  sixteenth  century 
were  solved  by  another  adaptation  of  the  theory  which  had  proved 
fatal  to  the  usefulness  of  the  clauses  in  favour  of  the  creditor  or  his 
nominee.1  The  old  French  law  had  allowed  that  a  stipulation  in 
favour  of  another,  in  the  form  of  a  promise  to  pay  the  bearer,  was 
valid.2  But  in  Roman  law  such  promises  in  favour  of  a  third 
person  were  not  valid  ;  and  therefore  the  school  of  the  commen- 
tators denied  their  validity.3  Promises  in  this  form  were,  however, 
comparatively  rare.  It  was  more  usual  in  the  Middle  Ages  for 
these  promises  to  be  drawn  up  in  favour  of  the  promisee  or  bearer.4 
These  promises  were  valid  because  the  promise  was  made  to  the 
other  contracting  party  as  well  as  to  the  bearer,  and  the  bearer 
could  be  regarded  as  a  person  solutioni  adjectus.  But  it  followed 
that  he  had  no  original  or  independent  right  of  action  on  the  con- 
tract.5 This  solution  was,  after  a  period  of  controversy,  adopted  in 
France,  and  ousted  the  older  customary  law,  which  had  allowed 
the  bearer  an  original  and  independent  right  of  action.6 

mercatori   Hamburgensi  faciendam,  debitori    suo  Lubecensi  novum  creditorem  con- 
stituere  potest  vice  sua ;    rursumque  fieri  potest  ut  huic  tertio.      Hamburgensi  novus 
quoque  constituatur  creditor ;  quam  delegationem  stylus  et  observantia  mercatorum 
vocat  inductionem." 
1  Above  121. 

3  Debray,  op.  cit.  31-32,  citing  the  custumal  of  Anjou  and  Maine;  above   117 
n.  5- 

3  Brunner,  op.  cit.  140 :  "  Bartolus,  Baldus  et  d'autres  jurisconsultes  font,  dans 
les  contrats  qui  ont  pour  objet  le  paiement  a  faire  a  un  tiers,  une  distinction  entre  le 
verbnm  obligativum  sen  obligationis,  promissionis  stipulations,  d'un  cote,  et  le  vcrbv.m 
executivum  sen  executionis,  d'autre  cote.  Si  la  stipulation  etait  concue  dans  ces 
termes  :  promittis  Mi  quod  dabis  Mi  ?  le  vcrbum  obligationis  portait  sur  le  tiers  et  la 
stipulation  gtait  regarded  comme  nulle.  La  stipulation  portait-elle :  promittis  mihi  ut 
dabis  Titio  ?  le  vcrbum  obligationis  se  rapportait  au  stipulant,  le  verbum  executivum 
au  tiers  et  le  contrat  etait  valable  "  ;  after  a  period  of  hesitation  it  would  seem  that  in 
France  a  promise  made  to  the  bearer  simply  was  treated  as  a  promise  to  the  promisee 
or  bearer,  ibid  160,  161. 
*  Ibid  148. 

5Straccha,  De  Adjecto,  Ft.  iv  8.  1  (Tractatus  Juris  vi  Pt.  I,  400):  "  Quaero, 
octavo,  solent  mercatores  se  debitores  constituere  in  haec  verba : — Lucius  Titius 
obligavit  se  Maevio  ad  mille  ex  causa  mercium  habitarum,  solvereque  promisit 
calendis  Febuariis  eidem  Maevio,  seu  ei  qui  chirographum  exhibuerit,  et  (ut  ipsi 
dicunt)  a  chi  il  presentara.  Finge  modo  Sempronium  habere  chirographum,  et  exhibere. 
Num  adjectus  constitutus  censeatur,  seu  magis  jus  agendi  Sempronio  competat  ? 
Quaestio  hasc  et  quotidiana  et  utilis  est  valde,  in  qua  prima  fronte  respondendum 
videatur  adjectum  Sempronium  constitutum  .  .  .  unde  sequitur  hunc  petitionem  non 
habere  "  ;  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  7.  41  :  "  Etiam  si  adjectus  haberet  penes  se 
scripturam,  in  qua  stat  adjectus,  illamque  in  judicio  produceret,  quia  ilia  habitio  et 
productio  non  sunt  apta  ad  acquirendum  obligationem,  et  consequenter  remaneret 
adjectus,  qui  nomine  proprio  non  potest  agere." 

6  Brunner,  op.  cit.  139-147  ;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1438-1439. 


124  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

This  development  was  assisted  by  the  fact  that  even  in  the  old 
customary  law  Roman  phrases  importing  agency  appeared.  Pay- 
ment was  to  be  made  to  X  or  bearer  or  agent.1  Gradually  more  and 
more  stress  was  laid  upon  these  phrases.  The  bearer  ceased  to  be 
described,  as  some  of  the  older  authorities  describe  him,  as  an 
agent  of  a  very  peculiar  kind,  in  that  his  authority  need  not  be 
proved  and  could  not  be  revoked.2  He  sank  to  the  position  of  an 
ordinary  agent.  The  result  was  that,  whether  he  was  regarded 
as  a  person  adjectus  solntioni,  or  as  an  agent,  he  had  no  independent 
right  of  action.  In  order  to  sue  he  must  prove,3  or  it  must  be 
presumed,4  either  that  he  has  been  appointed  the  agent  of  the 
creditor,  or  that  the  creditor  has  transferred  to  him  his  rights  by 
making  him  a  procurator  in  rem  suam.5 

The  result  was  that  the  negotiable  character  of  these  instru- 
ments disappeared.  If  the  bearer  sued  as  agent  his  authority  to 
sue  must  be  proved,  and  it  could  be  revoked.  In  any  case  it  was 
revoked  by  the  death  of  the  creditor — "  home  mort  n'a  porteur  de 
lettres." 6  If  he  sued  as  transferee  an  act  of  transfer  must  be  proved 
— "un  simple  transport  ne  saisit  point,"  i.e.  the  mere  delivery  of 
the  instrument  gives  the  bearer  no  right  to  sue  for  the  debt ;  and 
the  transfer  must  be  notified  to  the  debtor.7     Before  notification  of 

1  Brunner,  op.  cit,  155  :  "  11  est  tres  probable  que  la  clause  an  porteur  et  procureur 
.  .  .  doit  son  origine  aux  tendances  faites  pour  mettre  hors  doute  Taction  contestee  du 
porteur  par  l'addition  du  mot  procureur,  parce  qu'une  disposition  des  Institutes  regarde 
comme  valable  la  stipulation  mihi  ant  procuratori  /nco." 

2  Ibid  39-49. 

3Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  7.  41 :  "  Intelligo  tamen  quod  non  potest  [sc.  petere] 
proprio  nomine,  secus  autem  nomine  procuratorio." 

4Straccha,  op.  cit.  Pt.  iv  8.  8-10,  admits  that  if  a  person  produced  an  instrument 
authorizing  payment  to  be  made  to  the  bearer,  a  presumption  of  agency  might  arise 
from  the  possession  of  the  instrument,  and  that  such  person  could  sue  without  being 
obliged  to  give  the  cautio  de  rato ;  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  7.  55,  agrees,  though 
it  appears  (ibid  55-66)  that  the  point  was  controverted ;  but  he  concludes,  "  quicquid 
possit  dici  in  puncto  juris  non  est  recedendum  ab  extensione  quia  servatur  in  praxi  "  ; 
for  similar  rules  in  France,  see  Brunner,  op.  cit.  142-144 ;  but  this  was  only  a  pre- 
sumption which  could  be  rebutted,  e.g.  if  it  were  proved  that  the  creditor  had  for- 
bidden the  debtor  to  pay  the  bearer,  ibid  144. 

5  Straccha,  op.  cit.  Pt.  iv  17.  36  (Tractatus  Juris  vi  Pt.  I  404b) :  "  Reliquum  est 
ut  illud  non  ignoremus  et  ipsi  adjecto  actionem  competere  quando  constitutus  esset 
adjectus  in  rem  suam";  Brunner,  op.  cit.  146,  147,  citing  Dumoulin  and  Charondas 
de  Caron  ;  the  latter,  commenting  on  Bouteiller,  Somme  Rurale,  says  :  "  Ce  qu'il 
diet  icy  du  porteur  de  lettres  mihi  probari  non  potest  .  .  .  faudroit  pour  agir  en  son 
nom  et  en  exclure  le  principal  crdancier  qu'il  eut  cession  et  transport  de  luy  ant 
mandatas  actiones.     Et  ainsi  nous  en  usons." 

fi  This  maxim  appears  in  both  parts  of  a  collection  of  Parisian  judgments,  customs, 
and  maxims  by  Jean  Desmares  which  comes  from  the  latter  half  of  the  fourteenth 
century,  Brunner,  op.  cit.  49  ;  it  is  quite  contrary  to  the  rules  contained  in  the  first  part 
of  that  compilation,  and  other  writers,  e.g.  Bouteiller,  deny  it,  or  explain  it :  "  Elle 
n'a  done  pas  toujours  et&  en  vigueur  dans  le  droit  francais  :  elle  doit,  au  contraire, 
son  origine  a  l'application  faite  aux  titres  au  porteur  des  principes  du  droit  romain  sur 
mandat,"  ibid  50. 

7  For  this  maxim  and  its  meaning  see  ibid  27-29;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1435- 
1436  ;  it  appears  in  the  Coutume  de  Paris  of  1510,  art.  170,  and  its  meaning,  as  ex- 
plained  in    La   Nouvelle   Coutume  of  15S0,    art,   108,  is  that  mere   delivery  of  the 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         125 

the  transfer  to  the  debtor,  the  debtor  can  pay  the  transferor ;  and 
a  later  transferee,  who  is  the  first  to  give  notice,  can  gain  priority 
over  an  earlier  transferee  who  has  omitted  to  give  notice.  From 
this  point  of  view  some  lawyers  expressly  contrasted  a  transfer  of 
property,  for  which  a  mere  traditio  sufficed,  with  the  transfer  of  a 
debt,  for  which  a  mere  delivery  of  the  instrument  creating  the  debt 
did  not  suffice.1  Finally,  whether  the  bearer  sues  as  agent  or  as 
transferee,  the  defences  good  against  the  creditor  are  good  as 
against  him.2 

It  is  hardly  necessary  to  say  that  the  commercial  world  was 
seriously  inconvenienced  by  these  developments  of  legal  doctrine. 
The  older  instruments  made  payable  to  the  creditor  or  his  nominee 
had  disappeared,  and  given  place  to  these  instruments  payable 
to  bearer ;  and  now  the  negotiable  character  of  these  instruments 
to  bearer  had  been  destroyed.  The  merchants  at  first  had  recourse 
to  instruments  in  which  the  name  of  the  creditor  was  left  blank,  so 
that  the  ultimate  transferee  could  fill  in  his  own  name.3  But  in 
France  these  instruments  were  declared  illegal  by  several  decrees 
of  the  Parlement  of  Paris;4  and  in  1716  instruments  payable  to 
the  bearer  only  (except  those  issued  by  the  state  or  by  Law's 
bank)  were  declared  to  be  illegal.5  But  in  1721  it  was  found 
necessary7  to  repeal  the  edict  of  17 16,  and  to  permit  expressly 

instrument  will  not  operate  as  an  assignment  without  notice  to  the  debtor  or  some 
act  equivalent  thereto  ;  its  origin  is  not  very  clear  ;  under  the  influence  of  the  canon 
and  civil  law  the  instrument  constituting  the  debt  came  to  be  regarded  as  the  proof  of 
the  debt  merely,  not  the  debt  itself,  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1436  n.  3  ;  Brunner,  op.  cit. 
180,  181 ;  it  followed  that  a  mere  transference  of  the  instrument  could  not  trans.'er  the 
right  to  collect  the  debt — something  more  was  needed,  equivalent  to  a  livery  of  seisin 
in  the  case  of  property  ;  in  France,  as  in  England,  some  physical  act  was  needed  to 
transfer  an  incorporeal  thing,  such  as  a  rent,  vol.  iii  97-99 ;  Brunner  suggests  that 
this  rule  was  applied  to  debts — notice  to  the  debtor  being  recognized  as  a  sort  of  livery 
of  seisin.  We  thus  get  a  curious  parallel  to  the  English  rules  as  to  the  effect  of  notice 
given  by  the  assignee  of  a  chose  in  action  to  the  debtor,  and  the  rule  in  Dearie  v.  Hall 
(1828)  3  Russ.  1  as  to  the  effect  of  notice  to  the  trustees  upon  the  priority  of  equitable 
charges  on  a  trust  fund  of  chattels  personal ;  the  history  of  the  latter  rule  would  seem  to 
show  that  it  was  arrived  a:  quite  independently,  see  Ward  v.  Duncombe  [1893]  A.C. 
per  Lord  Macna^hten  ;  perhaps  the  existence  of  this  foreign  parallel  shows  that  there 
is  more  substantial  justice  in  it  than  Lord  Macnaghten  was  inclined  to  allow. 

1  Straccha,  De  Adjecto,  Pt.  iv  8.  3,  cites  authority  for  the  proposition  that  traditio 
suffices  for  corporeal  things,  "sed  si  traderem  tibi  instrumentum  in  quo  continetur 
nomen  debitoris  mei  ex  traditione  hujusmodi  instrumenti  non  videor  actionem  cessisse, 
•quae  mihi  contra  debitorem  meum  competebat " ;  but  he  does  not  agree  with  this, 
and  points  out  that  the  cession  of  such  an  instrument  animo  donandi  may  operate  as 
a  cession  of  the  right  of  action  ;  or,  if  the  animus  donandi  is  not  proved,  it  may  raise  a 
presumption  that  the  assignee  has  been  made  the  agent  of  the  assignor  to  sue  for  the 
debts — but  it  is  clear  that  the  mere  transfer  will  not  enable  the  assignee  to  sue  in  his 
own  name. 

2  Brunner,  op.  cit.  144,  156-157 ;  as  he  says  (ibid  147),  "  les  titres  au  porteur 
furent  mis  au  meme  rang  que  les  titres  a  personne  denommee  "  ;  for  his  position  see 
above  123. 

3  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1438-1439 ;  Brunner,  op.  cit.  159. 

4  Ibid.  5  Ibid. 


126  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

instruments  payable  to  bearer.1  Long  before  this,  however,  the 
development  of  the  negotiable  character  of  the  bill  of  exchange 
had  supplied  the  want  created  by  the  destruction  of  the  negotiable 
character  of  these  older  documents. 

(2)  The  origin  and  development  of  the  bill  of  exchange. 

In  dealing  with  this  much  controverted  subject  I  shall  consider 
(i)  the  mediaeval  contract  of  cambium  ;  (ii)  the  machinery  devised 
for  giving  effect  to  this  contract ;  and  (iii)  the  development  of 
the  negotiable  character  of  the  bill  of  exchange. 

(i)  The  medieval  contract  of  cambium. 

The  contract  of  cambium  was  a  special  variety  of  the  in- 
nominate contract  permutatio  ;  for  whilepermutalio  was  concerned 
with  exchange  generally,  cambium  was  concerned  with  the  special 
case  of  the  exchange  of  money  for  money.  Baldus  neatly  expressed 
the  difference  between  them  when  he  said  that  permutatio  was 
a  contract  by  which  a  species  of  one  genus  was  exchanged  for  a 
species  of  another  genus,  while  cambium  was  a  contract  by  which  a 
species  of  one  genus  was  exchanged  for  another  species  of  the  same 
genus.2  As  trade  expanded,  and  as  the  machinery  of  trade  grew 
more  elaborate,  this  contract  tended  to  occupy  a  sphere  of  ever- 
increasing  importance,3  and  to  develop  a  number  of  different  forms 
— some,  according  to  mediaeval  notions,  lawful,  and  others  unlawful. 
We  must  here  notice  three  of  the  most  important  of  these  forms. 

{a)  It  might  be  merely  a  contract  by  which  A  bargains  to  give 
B  coins  of  one  denomination  in  return  for  coins  of  another  denomi- 
nation {cambium  minutum).  There  was  nothing  illegal  in  this 
transaction  even  if  A  made  a  small  profit  on  it.4  In  England  it 
was  not  a  trade  in  which  anyone  could  engage.  Till  Henry 
VIII. 's  reign  it  was  in  the  hands  of  exchangers  authorized  by  the 
king.5  After  his  reign  the  trade  was  thrown  open;  and  state 
control  was  never  resumed,  though  the  project  of  resuming  it  was 

1  "  Nous  voulons,  etc.  .  .  .  qu'en  tous  commerces  et  negotiations  que  pourront 
faire  nos  subjets  pour  pret  d'argent,  vente  de  marchandises  ou  autrement,  ils  puissent 
et  qu'il  leur  soit  loisibls  d'en  stipuler  par  lettre  ou  billet  le  payement  au  porteur  sans 
denomination  de  personnes  certaines,"  cited  Brunner,  op.  cit.  160. 

2  Cited  Marquardus,  op.  cit.  ii  12,  22,  "  hoc  tantum  interesse  inter  cambium  et 
permutationem  quod  haec  propria  sit  speciei  ad  speciem,  illud  autem  speciei  quoque  ad 
genus  " ;  cp.  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  1,  Quaest.  iv  1,  2. 

3 «'  Quinimo  cambia  adeo  sunt  Reipublicae  utilia  et  necessaria,  ut  si  cambia 
cessarent,  omnia  pene  mercaturae  officia  dissiparentur  ac  destituerentur,"  Scaccia,  op. 
cit.  §  1,  Quaest.  vi  14. 

4  Thomas  De  Vio,  De  Cambiis  1.  1  (Tractatus  Juris  vi  Pt.  I.  405) :  "  Vocatur  autem 
cambium  minutum  quum  campsor  pro  aureo  ducato  monetam  dat  consuetam  in  patria 
ilia  expendi,  vel  e  converso,  aliquid  minus  dando  quam  recipiat.  Hoc  enim  continet 
naturalem  aequitatem,  ex  quo  quod  industria  et  opere  campsoris  ratio  habenda  est." 

5  Cunningham,  Industry  and  Commerce  i  283-284,  362,  432  n.  6;  Malynes,  Lex 
Mercatoria  260,  261;  Tawney,  Wilson  on  Usury  138-141. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         127 

favoured  by  Malynes,  and  several  attempts  were  made  to  adopt  it, 
the  last  of  which  was  in  1627.1  Abroad  this  business  was  largely 
in  the  hands  of  the  banks ;  and  in  England,  in  the  early  seven- 
teenth century,  it  seems  to  have  got  into  the  hands  of  members 
of  the  Goldsmiths'  Company,2  who,  as  we  shall  see,3  shortly  after 
this  period  began  to  do  a  certain  amount  of  banking  business. 

(£)  Under  the  names  of  cambium  siccum  and  cambium  fictivum 
the  contract  was  entered  into  in  order  to  circumvent  the  prohibi- 
tion of  usury ;  and  these  varieties  of  the  contract  were  unlawful. 
They  did  not  cease  to  be  used  when  the  usury  laws  permitted 
moderate  interest,4  for  they  could  be  employed  to  conceal  the  fact 
that  more  than  the  statutory  rate  of  interest  was  being  charged. 
Wilson's  treatise  on  usury  gives  us  a  very  clear  account  of  cambium 
siccum.  This  "secke  or  drye exchange,"  he  tells  us,5  "is  practised 
when  one  doth  borrowe  money  by  exchaunge  for  a  strange  region, 
at  longer  or  shorter  distaunce  of  time  .  .  .  not  myndynge  to  make 
anye  reall  payment  abroade,  but  compoundeth  with  the  exchanger 
to  have  it  returned  backe  agayne,  accordyng  as  the  exchaunge 
shall  passe  from  thence  to  London,  for  such  distaunce  of  time  as 
they  were  agreed  upon  :  and  yet  to  colour  this  matter,  there  shall 
billes  of  exchange  be  devised  and  sent  to  some  of  his  frendes  that 
lent  the  money  by  exchaunge,  with  letters  of  advise,  to  return  the 
byls  back  againe,  and  a  testimoniall  howe  the  exchaunge  commeth 
from  thence  .  .  .  which  retourninge  of  billes  by  testimoniall,  doth 
ever  cost  the  partye  that  dealeth  with  this  sorte  of  exchaunge, 
after  the  rate  of  sixteene  and  twenty  in  the  hundred  for  the  yere 
.  .  .  and  some  time  above  five  and  twenty  or  thirty  in  the  hundred 
for  the  yere.  And  bylles  by  this  kinde  of  exchaunge  are  made 
...  for  a  colour  onelie  to  get  the  parties  hand  to  them,  to  shew 
(if  neede  be)  that  suche  moneye  so  lente,  was  taken  up  for  him  by 
exchaunge,  the  said  billes  being  never  sent  out  of  London."  Cam- 
bium fictivum  seems  to  have  been  a  loan  at  usurious  interest,  dis- 
guised under  the  form  of  a  sale  of  goods  in  return  for  a  price 
which,  being  supposed  to  have  been  borrowed  abroad,  was  there- 
fore enhanced  by  the  costs  of  exchange.  Malynes  gives  us  a  good 
description  of  this  device  6  A  merchant,  he  tells  us,  not  being  able 
to  borrow  money,  is  driven  to  buy  goods  "  for  a  shift"  The  per- 
sons to  whom  he  applies  for  a  loan,  "  feign  that  they  have  need  of 
money,  and  must  sell  their  commodities  for  ready  money,  provided 
always  (say  they  with  loving  protestations)  we  will  pleasure  you 
thus  far,  look  what  the  goods  come  unto,  we  will  take  it  up  for  you 

1  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  164 ;  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Documents 
ii  167-173  ;  Tudor  and  Stuart  Proclamations  i  no.  1512  ;  below  185. 

2  Tudor  and  Stuart  Proclamations  i  no.  15 12. 

s  Below  185-186.  *  Above  10S-110. 

5  At  ft*.  117b,  uSa ;  see  above  106  n.  8.  ■*  Lex  Mercatoria,  261. 


128  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

by  exchange  for  Venice,  Lyons,  or  some  other  place,  so  as  you  will 
pay  us  for  exchange,  rechange,  or  any  other  incident  charges  : 
whereunto  the  merchant  agreeing,  then  shall  he  be  sure  to  pay 
soundly  for  the  use  of  the  money,  and  lose  exceedingly  upon  the 
wares." 

(c)  Historically  the  most  important  variety  of  cambium  was  the 
contract  by  which  A  agreed  with  B  to  transport  a  sum  of  money 
from  one  place  to  another,  and  to  deliver  it  safe  at  its  destination.1 
It  is,  historically,  the  most  important,  because  the  devices  by  which 
the  risks  of  physical  transportation  were  avoided  have  a  close  con- 
nection with  the  origins  of  many  of  the  institutions  of  the  modern 
world  of  commerce,  and  of  many  important  branches  of  commercial 
law.  In  particular  it  must  be  regarded  as  the  direct  ancestor  of 
the  two  institutions  with  which  we  are  concerned  in  this  section 
and  the  next — the  modern  mechanism  of  exchange  and  banking. 

So  soon  as  commerce  between  distant  nations  began  to  be 
developed,  it  became  clear  that  some  system  of  adjusting  accounts 
was  a  far  safer  and  easier  way  of  making  payments  in  distant  places 
than  the  primitive  method  of  handing  over  the  actual  money  due. 
And,  by  the  end  of  the  twelfth  and  the  beginning  of  the  thirteenth 
centuries,  the  various  parts  of  the  machinery  needed  for  making 
these  adjustments  were  at  hand.  The  lawyers  and  the  merchants 
soon  showed  that  they  had  sufficient  ingenuity  to  assemble  them. 

In  the  first  place,  the  exchangers,  whose  business  it  was  to  give 
coins  of  one  state  in  exchange  for  the  equivalent  value  of  coins  of 
another  state,  were  necessarily  experts  in  calculating  the  compara- 
tive value  of  the  various  debits  and  credits  owed  by  or  to  the 
merchants  of  different  countries,  and  in  expressing  them  in  the 
coinages  of  different  states.2  It  was  only  natural  that  merchants 
who  owed  money  to  foreign  creditors  should  entrust  the  exchangers 
with  the  money  needed  to  make  their  payments,  and  authorize  them 
to  pay  it  over ;  and,  conversely,  that  merchants  entitled  to  receive 
money  from  foreign  debtors  should  authorize  the  exchangers  to  re- 
ceive it  and  pay  it  over  to  them.  In  the  second  place,  instruments 
which  were  made  payable  to  the  creditor  or  his  agent,  or  to  the 
creditor  or  bearer,3  or  instruments  which  authorized  payment  to  be 
made  either  by  the  debtor  or  by  his  agent,  afforded  a  convenient 

1  Huvelin,  Travaux  regents  sur  l'histoire  de  la  Lettre  de  Change  4,  5 — it  is  there 
pointed  out  that  the  term  Cambium  has  (1)  a  large  sense  when  used  to  mean  all 
transactions  relating  to  money — "  contrats  sur  agent  et  sur  credit  par  opposition  aux 
transactions  portant  sur  des  marchandises  " ;  and  (2)  a  narrow  sense  in  which  it 
means  the  contract  to  transport  money  from  place  to  place;  this  transport  might 
either  be  "  ad  riscum  maris  et  gentium,"  i.e.  the  cairier  takes  no  risks,  or  "salvum 
in  terra,"  i.e.  the  carrier  undei takes  the  risks  of  carriage ;  and  "  c'est  la  derniere  forme 
qui  porte  presque  exclusivement,  d'assez  bonne  heure,  le  nom  d-  cambium." 

2 See  Huvelin,  Le  Droit  des  Marches  et  des  Foires,  543544- 

3  Above  115-121. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         129 

means  by  which  these  payments  could  be  made  to  or  by  these  ex- 
changers. The  exchanger  was  appointed  the  agent  or  nuntius  of 
the  creditor  or  debtor,  and  was  the  bearer  of  the  instrument.  In 
the  third  place,  the  great  fairs  afforded  such  convenient  meeting 
places  for  the  adjustment  of  these  accounts,  that  it  was  a  common 
practice  to  make  debts  payable  at  these  fairs.  Thus,  from  an  early 
date,  they  became  the  clearing  houses  of  Europe.  The  earliest 
fairs  to  fulfil  this  function  were  the  fairs  of  Champagne.1  When 
they  began  to  decline,  in  the  course  of  the  fourteenth  century,  the 
fairs  of  Lyons,  Anvers,  and  Genoa  succeeded  to  this  position.2 

Professor  Huvelin  has  so  clearly  and  succinctly  explained  the 
manner  in  which  this  machineiy  was  used  to  obviate  the  necessity 
of  a  physical  transportation  of  money,  that  I  cannot  do  better  than 
copy  his  description3: — "That  we  may  the  better  understand  this 
system,  let  us  take  an  example.  Genoa  has  business  relations  with 
London  and  Geneva.  Goods  have  been  bought  and  sold  in  all 
these  places.  From  all  of  them  there  are  debts  to  be  recovered. 
To  effect  this  object  is  it  necessary  to  resort  to  the  dangerous  and 
costly  process  of  transporting  money?  The  merchants  soon  dis- 
covered the  expedient  of  regulating  their  business  relations  by 
means  of  letters  of  exchange  payable  at  the  same  fair.  They 
stipulated  for  letters  of  exchange  payable  at  the  fairs  of  Bar,  of 
Provins,  &c.  Suppose  that  a  Genoese  was  obliged  to  receive  a 
hundred  livres  from  his  London  correspondent.  The  latter  promised 
to  pay  this  sum  at  the  fair  of  Bar,  for  instance,  and  remitted  to  the 
Genoese  the  document  in  which  he  acknowledged  that  he  owed  this 
sum  and  promised  to  pay  at  a  fixed  date  at  the  fair  of  Bar.  He 
then  chose  in  London  a  banker  going  to  the  fair  of  Bar,  to  whom 
he  gave  an  authority  to  pay  the  debt  in  his  name  when  it  fell  due. 
The  Genoese  on  his  side  chose  at  Genoa  a  banker  going  to  the  same 
fair.  Thus  the  two  bankers  played  the  part  of  nuntii  or  missi  of 
these  two  parties.  When  they  came  to  the  fair  the  one  was  the 
bearer  of  an  order  to  pay,  the  other  of  an  order  to  receive  payment 
of  the  debt 

"  But  each  of  these  bankers  who  came  to  the  fair  had  many  pay- 
ments to  make  and  to  receive  ;  and  the  duty  to  make  and  the  right 
to  receive  these  payments  originated  in  obligations  made  in  a  large 
number  of  places.  If  the  bankers  of  Genoa  and  London  were 
obliged  to  pay  and  receive  exactly  the  same  sums  from  each  place, 
the  settlement  would  be  very  easy,  since  all  the  debts  would  be 

1  Le  Droit  des  Marches  et  des  Foires,  556,  "  C'est  un  usage  tres  general  depuis  le 
xne  siecle,  de  souscrire  des  effets  de  change  payables  en  foire.  Les  foires  de  Cham- 
pagne sont  de  bonne  heure,  selon  le  mot  de  Goldschmidt,  le  domicile  de  change  de 
toute  V Europe.  Nous  possedons  des  lettres  de  change  de  1190,  1248,  1251,  etc.,  pay- 
ables aux  foires  de  Champagne." 

3  Ibid.  3  Ibid  557-558. 

VOL.    VIII. — 9 


130  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

extinguished  by  set-off.  But  it  may  well  be,  and  this  is  the  most 
common  case,  that  one  of  these  places  owed  the  other  more  than  it 
is  entitled  to  receive.  Genoa,  for  instance,  may  have  an  adverse 
balance  as  against  London.  Therefore,  if  we  were  only  considering 
these  two  places,  there  would  be  a  considerable  debt  still  owing 
which  would  not  be  extinguished  by  set-off. 

"  But  these  two  places  are  not  the  only  places  represented  at  the 
fairs.  All  the  places  of  Western  Europe  are  represented  there. 
Now  if  Genoa  has  an  adverse  balance  as  against  London,  it  may 
well  have  a  favourable  balance  as  against  Ypres,  Paris,  or  Geneva. 
Genoa  has,  therefore,  a  balance  of  payments  to  receive  from  these 
places.  An  unfavourable  balance  on  the  one  side,  a  favourable 
balance  on  the  other,  obviously  admits  of  set  of.  Genoa  can  draw 
on  the  bankers  of  Paris,  Ypres,  or  Geneva  to  pay  her  London 
creditors.  The  sum  to  be  liquidated  will  be  the  difference  left  after 
all  these  operations  have  been  carried  out.  Thus  .  .  .  thanks  to 
the  principle  of  set-off,  thanks  to  the  practice  of  making  letters  of 
exchange  payable  at  the  same  fair,  the  work  of  making  payments 
will  be  simplified  and  shortened.  The  amount  to  be  paid  in  money 
will  generally  be  insignificant." 

Now,  it  is  clear  that  it  is  to  these  developments  of  the  contract 
of  cambium,  that  we  must  look  for  the  origins  of  the  bills  of  ex- 
change and  the  banks  of  our  modern  commercial  life.  We  shall 
see  that  the  earliest  bills  of  exchange  were  instruments  devised  to 
obviate  the  risks  of  the  physical  transport  of  money  ;  and  that  the 
earliest  bankers  were  the  mediaeval  exchangers  who  dealt  in  money.1 
Merchants  who  wished  to  transport  money,  in  order  to  liquidate 
their  foreign  debts,  handed  over  the  necessary  sum  to  an  exchanger, 
and  he  drew  a  bill  upon  his  correspondent  or  agent  in  the  foreign 
country.  Conversely,  merchants  who  were  entitled  to  receive 
money  abroad,  made  an  exchanger  their  agent  to  receive  the 
money  due  on  these  bills.  To  these  exchangers,  therefore,  natur- 
ally fell  the  business  of  adjusting  accounts  between  different  coun- 
tries ;  and  it  was  through  the  use  made  by  them  of  these  bills  that 
they  developed  into  bankers,  to  whom  the  merchants  entrusted 
money  to  be  dealt  with  according  to  their  instructions.  Thus  the 
origins  of  bills  of  exchange  and  of  banking  are  almost  inseparably 
connected.  In  fact,  we  shall  see  that  it  is  to  the  commercial  needs 
which  originated  these  bills  of  exchange  that  we  must  look  for  the 
explanation  of  the  rise  and  growth  of  banks  and  banking.2 

It  is  clear  from  the  recently  published  Calendar  of  the  early 
rolls  of  the  Mayor's  Court  of  the  City  of  London 3  that  the  Italian 
merchants  in  England  were  making  use  of  this  machinery.      In 

1  Below  131-132,  177.  -  Below  177-178.  3  Edited  by  A.  N.  Thomas. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         131 

1 300  there  is  a  case  in  which  Geoffrey  Beble,  chaplain,  complained 
that  Antony,  rector  of  Hurtts,  while  staying  in  his  house,  had  stolen 
£17.  He  alleged  that  Antony  had  taken  the  money  to  Brachius 
Lumbard  of  the  Society  of  the  Pulci  of  Florence,  and  had  asked 
that  it  might  be  paid  out  to  him  by  the  Society  in  Paris.  It 
appeared  that  Brachius  had  received  the  money,  and  that  he  had 
given  Antony  a  letter  addressed  to  the  Society  of  Paris  asking 
them  to  pay  it  Brachius,  when  summoned,  "  admitted  the  receipt 
of  the  money,  and  said  that  it  had  not  been  paid  out  in  London 
or  Paris,  but  that  he  did  not  know  whether  it  had  been  paid  by 
the  Society  elsewhere.  As  the  said  Antony  was  not  in  Court,  and 
as  the  Society  in  Paris  had  written  to  the  other  Societies  not  to 
pay  the  money,  and  as  it  was  not  known  whether  any  other 
Society  had  already  paid,  Brachius  was  forbidden  to  pay  the 
money  until  further  orders."  l  The  letter  written  by  Brachius  to 
the  Society  at  Paris  was  clearly  a  bill  of  exchange,  and  the  later 
happenings  clearly  amounted  to  an  attempt  to  stop  the  bill.  In 
1305  there  is  another  case  in  which  the  same  machinery  of  pay- 
ment was  adopted.  Peter  de  Maners  sued  Vilanus  Stolde  and 
the  Society  of  the  Peruzzi  of  Florence  for  100  marks,  which  had 
been  entrusted  to  them  to  be  paid  at  Andvers  in  Brabant  a 
week  later,  or  failing  that  in  London  at  Midlent.  The  receipt  of 
the  money  was  admitted,  but  it  was  alleged  that  "  they  had  sent 
a  letter  to  a  partner,  John  Vyleyn,  at  Andvers,  by  John  de  Maners, 
the  plaintiffs  brother,  to  pay  the  money,  which  they  supposed 
had  been  done ;  but  if  the  plaintiff  would  return  the  letter  and 
prove  that  payment  had  not  been  made,  they  would  satisfy  him." 2 
Similarly  in  a  case  of  1 302  there  is  a  reference  to  payment  through 
an  agent  at  the  fair  of  Turruk.a  These  instances,  I  think,  make  it 
clear  that  this  machinery  of  payment  through  bills  of  exchange 
was  well  known  at  the  beginning  of  the  fourteenth  century. 

At  this  point  we  must  return  to  the  contract  of  cambium,  and 
examine  in  detail  the  manner  in  which  the  machinery  for  giving 
effect  to  this  variety  of  it,  gave  rise  to  our  modern  bills  of 
exchange. 

(ii)  The  machinery  devised  for  giving  effect  to  the  contract  of 
cambium. 

The  machinery  devised  for  giving  effect  to  this  contract  of 
cambium  was  the  bill  of  exchange.  The  earliest  bills  of  exchange 
are  in  the  form  of  a  letter  addressed  by  B  to  C,  asking  C  to  pay 
to  a  third  person  D  a  sum  of  money,  which  A  has  entrusted  to  B 
for  this  purpose.  This  letter  is  handed  by  B  to  A,  who  sends  it 
on  to  D ;  and  D  presents  it    for  payment  to  C.     We  have  an 

1  Op.  cit.  94.  -  Ibid  200-201.  3  Ibid  129. 


132  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

example  of  these  bills  as  early  as  1339;1  they  are  referred  to  in 
the  Florentine  statute  of  the  Calimala  of  1332  ;  and  the  English 
cases  in  the  Mayor's  court  would  seem  to  justify  us  in  assigning 
to  them  an  even  earlier  date.'2  It  is  clear,  therefore,  that  they 
were  known  in  Italy  at  the  beginning  of  the  fourteenth  century.3 
Whence  did  they  originate? 

On  this  point  it  cannot  be  said  that  there  is  yet  any  definite 
agreement.  But  to  my  mind  the  most  probable  hypothesis  is  that 
they  originated  in  the  method  employed  by  the  Italian  merchants 
who  had  entered  into  a  contract  to  transport  money.  Such  a 
contract  would  be  contained  in  an  instrumentum  ex  causa  camdu.* 
The  method  employed  to  carry  it  out  was  by  writing  a  "  letter  of 
payment"  to  a  correspondent  living  in  the  place  where  the  pay- 
ment was  to  be  effected.  In  favour  of  this  hypothesis  it  may  be 
remembered  that  the  earliest  specimens  of  bills  of  exchange  come 
from  Italy ;  that  their  wording,  when  they  appear  in  England  in 
the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries,  is  almost  identical 
with  the  wording  of  the  Italian  bills  of  the  fourteenth  century ; 
and  that  the  analogy  of  many  other  institutions  and  doctrines  of 
our  modern  commercial  and  maritime  law  would  lead  us  to  suppose 
that  it  was  in  Italy  that  this,  the  most  remarkable  institution 
of  our  commercial  law,  originated. 

That  this  is  the  most  probable  hypothesis  as  to  the  origin  of 
the  bill  of  exchange  will  be  clear,  if  we  look  at  some  of  the  other 
hypotheses  which  have  been  suggested.  But,  before  dealing  with 
these  hypotheses,  we  should  do  well  to  remember  that  in  this,  as 
in  other  branches  of  law,  the  argument  from  analogy  is  dangerous. 
It  is  quite  clear  that  so  soon  as  commerce  begins  in  any  degree  to 
develop,  methods  will  be  found  of  avoiding  the  risks  attendant 
upon  the  physical  transport  of  money.  These  methods  of  solving 
the  same  problem  will  naturally  possess  a  superficial  similarity. 
But  the  existence  of  this  similarity  is  very  far  from  proving  any 
derivative  relationship. 

In  the  first  place,  it  is  clear  that  there  is  nothing  in  Roman 
law  which  in  any  way  resembles  the  bill  of  exchange.  No  doubt 
the  adstipulatio,  the  delegation  and  the  novatio  could  be  made  to 

1  Below  135  n.  2.  2  Above  131. 

3Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  7  and  n.  4,  "  Les  lettres  .  .  .  sont  appelees 
lettere  di  pagamento  (lettres  de  paiement).  Theoriquement,  la  lettera  di  pagamento 
peut  servir  a  effectuer  le  paiement  de  toute  obligation,  quel  qu'en  soit  le  fait  gdn6rateur 
(p.  ex.  vente  des  marchandises,  commande,  etc.).  Et  le  statut  de  Calimala  de  1332 
constate  l'emploi  de  lettere  di  pagamento  di  mercantia,  acomendigia  etc.  Mais,  tres 
g6n£ralement,  dans  la  pratique,  elle  sert  a  effectuer  le  paiement  d'une  obligation  n£e 
d'un  contrat  de  transport  d'argent.  Elle  prend  alors  le  nom  de  lettera  di  pagamento 
di  cambio,  et,  plus  brievement,  de  lettera  di  cambio  .  .  .  On  reconnait  dans  la  lettera 
di  pagamento  la  premiere  forme  de  la  traite  moderne"  ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1440- 
1441. 

4  For  the  relation  of  this  instrumentum  to  the  letter  see  below  136-137. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT        133 

fulfil  some  of  the  functions  fulfilled  by  the  bill  of  exchange ;  but 
we  cannot  find  in  the  classical  texts  any  institution  which  resembles 
it  in  form,  or  in  mode  of  operation.1  No  doubt  reasoning  based 
upon  such  topics  as  adstipulatio,  delegatio,  and  novatio,  was 
sometimes  used  by  the  civilians  of  the  fourteenth  and  fifteenth 
centuries  to  explain  the  legal  position  of  the  parties  to  a  bill  of 
exchange.  They  naturally  tried  to  explain,  in  the  technical 
language  of  their  own  system,  the  legal  relations  created  by  these 
commercial  instruments,  just  as  in  the  sixteenth  century  the 
English  common  lawyers  tried  to  explain  them  in  their  technical 
language.  But,  as  we  shall  see,  it  was  impossible  to  make  all 
their  incidents  fit  precisely  the  technical  conceptions  of  either 
system.  Under  both  systems  it  was  necessary  to  modify  these 
technical  conceptions  in  order  to  give  them  their  full  effect. 
Without  such  a  modification  (which,  as  we  have  seen,  the  school 
of  the  post-glossators  was  in  general  far  more  ready  to  make 
than  the  school  of  the  Renaissance  jurists)  neither  the  bill  of  ex- 
change, nor  certain  other  institutions  and  doctrines  of  our  modern 
commercial  law,  could  have  been  evolved.  As  we  have  seen,-  a 
too  rigid  adherence  to  these  technical  conceptions  destroyed  the 
negotiable  characteristics  which  the  mediaeval  instruments  to 
bearer  or  to  order  had  possessed. 

In  the  second  place,  claims  have  been  made  for  an  Arabic 
origin.3  It  is  certain  that  in  the  eighth  century  A.D.,  long  before 
anything  like  the  bill  of  exchange  appeared  in  Italy,  something 
very  much  like  the  modern  bill  of  exchange  was  known.  It  could 
pass  from  hand  to  hand  by  something  very  much  like  an  indorse- 
ment ;  and,  to  use  modern  terms,  the  payee  had  a  right  of  recourse 
against  the  drawer  in  the  event  of  non-payment  by  the  acceptor. 
The  influence  of  Arabic  conceptions  on  Western  commerce, 
especially  in  the  reign  of  PVederic  II.  (1212-1255),  is  undoubted.4 
The  evidence  of  language  alone  is  conclusive.5  But,  as  Professor 
Huvelin  has  pointed  out,  the  existence  of  this  analogous  Arabic 
institution  is  not  so  conclusive  as  it  might  at  first  sight  appear. 
The  Arabic  bill  is  far  more  fully  negotiable  than  the  Italian  bill 
of  the  thirteenth  century.  It  can  pass  indefinitely  from  hand  to 
hand  by  what  corresponds  to  an  indorsement ;  but  it  was  not  till 

1  Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  7.  2  Above  121-125. 

'For  a  very  full  discussion  and  explanation  of  this  theory  (put  forward  by 
Grasshoff,  Das  Wechselrecht  der  Araber)  see  Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  23-2S. 

4  See  ibid  27,  28  ;  cp.  Nys,  Les  Origines  du  droit  international,  160,  163,  281,  282. 

B  "  Au  moyen  age,  le  commerce  arabe,  tres  actif  et  tres  perfection^,  est  un  element 
fecondant  pour  le  commerce  d'Occident,  sur  lequel  il  marque  son  empreinte.  Signe 
caracteristique  de  cette  influence,  la  langue  du  commerce  occidental  est  pleine 
d'emprunts  a  l'arabe,  qui  remontent  a  cette  6poque  (Taraffuk  =  trafic  ;  awar  =  avarie  ; 
farda  =  fardeau ;  machsin  =  magasin  ;  tarha  =  tare  (poids) ;  ta'rif  =  tarif ;  divan  = 
douane ;  simsar  =  sensalis,  courtier),"  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  24. 


134  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

some  centuries  later  that  our  modern  bills  of  exchange  acquired 
this  quality.1 

In  the  third  place,  Dr.  Freundt 2  has  put  forward  the  theory 
that,  among  the  northern  nations,  the  bill  of  exchange  may  have 
been  evolved  from  the  letters  patent  and  letters  close  by  which 
rulers  did  much  of  their  governmental  business — financial  or  other- 
wise ; 3  and  Professor  Jules  Valery  advocates  a  theory  closely 
analogous  to  that  of  Dr.  Freundt.4  He  too  finds  the  origins  of  the 
bill  of  exchange  in  documents  used  in  public  law,5  such  as  letters 
patent  or  letters  close  or  writs  of  liberate,"  dating  from  the  thirteenth 
century  or  earlier.  In  these  documents  the  king  or  other  ruler 
orders  an  official,  having  control  of  his  money,  to  pay  a  fixed  sum 
to  a  payee  or  his  agent  producing  the  document."  Professor  Valery 
points  out  that  the  rulers  of  states,  especially  at  the  time  of  the 
Crusades,8  often  had  occasion  to  remit  large  sums  of  money.9  He 
thinks  it  likely  that  the  laconic  and  imperative  style  of  these  state 
documents  suggested  the  form  taken  by  the  bill  of  exchange ; 10  and 
that  documents  thus  drawn  up  were  distinguished  by  their  style 
from  ordinary  letters  requesting  the  recipient  to  make  a  payment.11 

But  we  must  distinguish  between  these  public  documents. 
Some  are  merely  instructions  to  a  royal  official  to  pay  a  royal 
debtor  ;  and,  as  Professor  Huvelin  has  pointed  out,12  the  economic 
function  of  the  bill  of  exchange  is  very  different  from  the  economic 
function  of  many  letters  patent  and  letters  close  executed  with  this 
object.  The  primary  function  of  the  first  was  to  operate  as  a 
transport  of  money  in  the  interest  of  the  creditor.     The  primary 

I  Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  27.  2  Das  Wechselrecht  der  Postglossatoren. 

3  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  g-11. 

4  Une  Traite  de  Philippe  le  Bel,  Contribution  a  l'histoire  de  la  lettre  de  change. 

5  Op.  cit.  5-7,  25-28,  35-45. 

6  Ibid  17,  18  :  "  Depuis  assez  longtemps  deja  des  auteurs  qui  se  sont  occupe"s  de 
l'histoire  de  la  lettre  de  change  ont  signals  l'existence  de  titres,  extremement  nom- 
breux,  connus  sous  le  nom  de  liberate,  par  lesquels  les  rois  d'Angleterre  avaient 
coutume  d'ordonnancer  les  payements  a  faire  avec  les  deniers  de  la  Couronne." 

7  The  following  is  the  document  which  Professor  Valery  takes  as  his  text : 
' '  Phillippus  Dei  gratia  Francorum  rex  ballivo  Caleti  vel  eius  locum  tenenti  salutem. 
Mandamus  vobis  quatinus  Radulpho  de  St.  Oein  decenario  aut  eius  mandate  presentes 
litteras  defferenti  undecim  libras  et  decern  solidos  turonensium  in  quibus  eidem 
tenemur  de  residuo  tarn  vadiorum  suorum  in  facto  guerre  nostre  Vasconie  anno 
presenti  acquisitionem  quam  restauri  cujusdem  equi,  absque  dilacione  quacunque  ad 
instantem  mediam  quadragesimam  de  nostro  integre  persolvatis  quam  pecunie  summam 
in  nostris  computis  volumus  allocari  et  penes  vos  presentes  litteras  remanere.  Actum 
Parisius  die  lune  ante  Candelosam  anno  Domini  M°CC°  nonagesimo  sexto." 

8  In  connection  with  the  Crusades  it  is  interesting  to  note  that  the  Templars  in  the 
thirteenth  century  acted  as  royal  financial  agents,  and  that  they  developed  what  was 
essentially  a  deposit  banking  business,  and  an  exchange  business,  see  Bruce  William- 
son, History  of  the  Temple  chap  ii ;  if  they  had  survived,  the  Templars,  with  their 
various  branches  throughout  Europe,  might  have  developed  a  banking  and  exchange 
business  on  the  same  lines  as  the  great  Italian  financial  houses. 

9  Op.  cit.  14.  10  Ibid  26-28. 

II  Valery,  op.  cit.  40.  12  Travaux  regents,  etc.,  11. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         135 

function  of  the  second  (when  used  to  effect  the  payment  of  a  debt) 
was  often  to  effect  a  payment  in  a  place  most  convenient  to  the 
debtor.  It  is  no  doubt  true,  as  Professor  Valery  has  pointed  out, 
that  the  commercial  dealings  of  the  state  were  often  extensive ; 
and  the  forms  and  usages  of  the  state  machinery  may  have  had 
some  influence  on  the  forms  and  usages  of  the  commercial  world. 
On  the  other  hand,  it  is  at  least  as  likely  that  in  many  cases  the 
influence  was  reverse,  and  that  the  state  used  the  established 
mechanism  of  commerce.  Professor  Valery  admits  that  private 
letters,  written  in  the  ordinary  course  of  commercial  correspondence, 
were  used  to  do  the  same  work  as  these  public  or  quasi-public 
documents  ;  *  and  we  shall  see  that  the  forms  of  the  earliest  bills  of 
exchange  in  England  are  far  more  analogous  to  the  former  than 
to  the  latter  class  of  documents.2  No  doubt  at  all  periods  the 
necessities  of  the  state  have  had  a  great  influence  upon  the  develop- 
ment of  commercial  law;  but,  generally,  those  needs  have  been 
supplied  by  adaptations  of  existing  commercial  customs,  rather 
than  by  borrowing  from  the  machinery  of  the  state  an  idea  or  a 
form  wholly  new  to  the  merchants.  The  history  of  the  develop- 
ment, both  of  transferable  shares  in  joint  stock  companies,  and  of 
negotiable  instruments  in  England  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  supplies  an  illustration  of  this  truth.3  We  shall  see 
that  at  that  period  both  these  shares  and  bills  of  debt  and  bills  of 
exchange  were  part  of  the  ordinary  mechanism  of  commerce  in 
England.  But  there  is  no  doubt  that  their  development  was 
assisted  by  the  growth  of  the  system  of  borrowing  on  the  security 
of  the  revenue,  which,  after  the  Revolution,  gave  rise  to  the  Bank 
of  England  and  the  National  Debt  These  creditors  of  the  state 
owned  shares  in  the  stock  which  they  had  advanced  to  the  govern- 
ment, and  they  were  empowered  by  statute  to  transfer  these  shares.4 

1 "  La  redaction  de  ces  lettres  de  change  ne  pr^sente  aucune  particularite ;  leur 
style  ne  differe  en  rien  de  celui  des  missives  ordinaires ;  on  y  trouve  les  memes 
formules  de  politesse;  frequemment  elles  sont  relatives  a  plusieurs  objets  diff^rents. 
Elles  constituent  done  tout  simplement  une  partie  de  la  correspondance  commerciale. 
.  .  .  Voici  done  une  double  serie  de  titres  appartenant  a  la  meme  £poque  et  ayant  le 
meme  objet  puisqu'ils  se  ramenent  tous  a  des  delegations  consenties  par  un  creancier 
au  profit  d'un  de  ses  propres  creanciers.  Seulement  les  uns  sont  fournis  par  le  droit 
public,  tandis  que  les  autres  rentrent  uniquement  dans  le  domaine  du  droit  commercial," 
op.  cit.  25,  26-27. 

2  The  following  is  an  Italian  bill  of  exchange  of  the  year  1339,  cited  Valery,  op. 
cit  23  n.  2  :  "  Al  nome  di  Dio,  amen.  Bartalo  e  compagni,  Barna  da  Lucha  e  com- 
pagni  salute.  Di  Vignone,  Pagherete  per  questa  lettera  a  di  xx  di,  novembre  1339  a 
Landuccio  Busdraghi  e  compagni  da  Lucha  fiorini  trecento  dodici  e  tre  quarti  d'  oro 
per  cambio  di  fiorini  trecento  d'oro,  che  questo  di  della  fatta  n'avemo  da  Tancredi 
Bonaquinta  e  compagni,  a  raxione  di  iii  e  quarto  per  c.  alloro  vantaggio ;  e  ponete 
a  nostro  conto  e  ragione.  Fatta  di  v  d'ottobre  1339. — Francesco  Falconetti  ci  a 
mandati  a  paghare  per  voi  a  gli  Accianioli  scudi  ccxxx  d'oro.  Bartalo  Casini  e 
compagni  in  Pisa."  See  below  152-153  for  some  specimens  of  the  earliest  bills  of 
exchange  which  appear  in  the  English  records. 

3  Below  159-170,  211-212,  214,  *  Below  188,  211. 


136  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

Obviously  these  transferable  shares  helped  to  familiarize  the 
wealthier  classes  of  the  community  and  the  lawyers  with  the  idea 
of  transferable  choses  in  action  ;  while  the  Bank  of  England 
notes,  established  in  1696  by  the  same  statute  as  that  which 
established  the  National  Debt  and  the  Bank  of  England  itself,1 
familiarized  them  with  choses  in  action  which  were  soon  recognized 
as  negotiable.2  But  it  could  hardly  be  contended  that  the  idea  of 
a  joint  stock  divided  into  shares,  or  the  idea  of  a  negotiable 
instrument,  originated  in  the  fiscal  expedients  which  were  then 
adopted  by  the  state.  And  something  like  this,  I  think,  happened 
in  the  Middle  Ages.  State  needs  no  doubt  helped  the  develop- 
ment of  the  bill  of  exchange.  The  forms  of  public  documents  may 
possibly  have  influenced  its  form.  But  I  should  be  inclined  to 
take  the  view  that  the  idea  of  the  bill  of  exchange  originated  in 
the  customs  of  the  Italian  commercial  cities ; 3  and  there  is  no 
doubt  that  its  legal  development  took  place  under  the  influence  of 
the  Italian  commercial  lawyers.4 

I  think,  therefore,  that  the  origin  of  the  bill  of  exchange  must 
most  probably  be  sought  in  the  Italian  letter  of  payment.  At 
first  it  was  only  the  satellite,  so  to  speak,  of  a  formal  cautio  or 
instrumentum  ex  causa  cambii — the  contract  by  which  A  contracted 
with  B  to  transport  money  for  B  to  another  place,  in  order  that 
that  money  might  be  paid  over  to  C.  This  formal  contract  ex  causa 
cambii  is  simply  one  of  many  uses  to  which  these  cautiones  or  instru- 
ments were  put.5  This  instrument  is  described  by  Scaccia  as  a 
public  instrument,  whereby  the  person  receiving  money  for  exchange 
promises  to  pay  the  agreed  amount  of  the  money  to  be  exchanged 
to  another,  who  is  named  in  the  instrument  by  the  creditor  who  has 
advanced  the  money,  that  other  being  usually  the  correspondent 
of  the  creditor ;  and  he  further  promises  to  send  the  public  instru- 
ment to  the  creditor  ;  and,  if  he  does  not  fulfil  his  contract,  he 
promises  to  repay  to  the  creditor,  with  interest,  the  sum  received  in 
the  place  where  he  received  it.6     But,  for  the  purposes  of  exchange, 

1  Below  174  n.  2,  188.  2  Below  170-173. 

3  Cp.  Val£ry,  op.  cit.  22.  4  Below  137  seqq. 

5  "  Lorsqu'un  contrat  quelconque,  vente,  pret,  cambium  etc.  a  £te"  conclu,  il  arrive 
souvent  que  Ton  rgdige  un  instrument  pour  constater  les  obligations  qu'il  fait 
naitre  .  .  .  Un  pareil  instrument,  re"dige  pour  un  cambium,  ne  differe  pas  de  celui 
qui  serait  redige"  pour  une  vente  ou  pour  un  pret.  Seule  la  causa  du  titre  differe," 
Huvelin,  travaux  regents,  etc.,  5. 

6  Scaccia,  De  Commerciis  et  Cambiis  §  1,  Quaest.  v  II,  "  Primus  modus  concipiendi 
scripturam  in  contractu  cambii  est  per  instrumentum  publicum  ;  cum  scilicet  accipiens 
cambio  .  .  .  promittit  pretium  cambii  conventum  solvere  .  .  .  alicui  certae  personae,  in 
ipso  instrumento  a  creditore  nominatae,  qua?  solet  esse  correspondens  ipsius  creditoris, 
qui  dat  pecuniam  cambio,  et  ulterius  promittit  solutionis,  quam  faciat,  transmittere 
publicum  et  authenticum  testimonium  seu  fidem,  infra  certum  alium  terminum,  eidem 
qui  dedit  cambio,  in  tali  loco,  alias,  si  defecerit  in  non  solvendo,  et  in  solutionis  testi- 
monium non  transmittendo,  promittit  solvere  in  loco  contractus  eidem  creditori  una 
cum  interesse." 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         137 

this  formal  instrument  gradually  dropped  out,  and,  in  the  course  of 
the  fourteenth  century,  its  place  was  taken  by  the  letter  or  bill  by 
means  of  which  the  contract  of  transport  was  actually  fulfilled.1 
Thus,  by  that  date,  the  bill  of  exchange  had,  through  this  develop- 
ment of  mercantile  practice,  emerged  as  an  independent  contract 
possessing  some  very  peculiar  features  of  its  own.  It  therefore 
became  necessary  for  the  lawyers  to  elucidate  and  to  give  technical 
expression  to  the  legal  relations  subsisting  between  the  various 
parties  to  the  bill. 

That  we  may  understand  the  manner  in  which  they  approached 
this  pioblem,  it  will  be  perhaps  as  well  to  recall  the  part  played 
by  the  different  parties  to  the  bill. 

(i)  There  is  A,  who  wishes  to  remit  money  to  a  foreign  country 
to  be  paid  over  to  D  (the  payee),  (ii)  There  is  B  (the  drawer), 
probably  an  exchanger,  to  whom  A  pays  over  this  money  for  the 
purposes  of  transmission.  B,  thereupon,  to  carry  out  this  contract 
to  transmit  the  money,  writes  a  letter  to  C  (the  drawee),  who  lives 
in  this  foreign  country,  asking  him  to  pay  this  sum  of  money  to  D. 
(iii)  There  is  C  (the  drawee),  who,  on  being  requested  by  B  to  pay 
this  money  which  he  (B)  has  received  from  A,  admits  his  liability 
to  do  so  by  accepting  the  bill,  (iv)  There  is  D  (the  payee),  to 
whom  C  (the  acceptor)  has  been  requested  to  make  this  payment. 
Thus  it  was  necessary  to  consider  (a)  the  relations  of  the  person 
who  has  paid  over  the  money,  which  he  wishes  to  remit,  to  the 
drawer  who  has  received  it ;  (J?)  the  relations  of  the  drawer  and 
the  drawee ;  (c)  the  relations  of  the  acceptor  and  the  payee ;  (d) 
the  relations  of  the  payee  and  the  drawer. 

(a)  The  relations  of  the  person  who  has  paid  over  the  money, 
which  he  wishes  to  remit,  to  the  drawer  who  has  received  it. — It  is 
clear  that  the  drawer,  who  receives  money  under  these  circumstances, 
is  bound  by  his  contract  to  pay  the  money  to  the  person  designated 
by  him  who  has  handed  it  over  to  him  (the  drawer)  for  this  pur- 
pose. It  is  in  effect  a  constitutum  ;  and,  if  the  person  who  has 
handed  the  money  to  the  drawer  owes  the  money  to  the  payee 
(which  is  the  most  ordinary  case),  it  will  be  a  constitutum  debiti 
alieni.  According  to  ordinary  principles  of  Roman  law,  the 
drawer  is  bound  to  the  man  who  has  handed  him  over  the  money 
to  pay  it  to  the  payee.2 

1  Debray,  op.  cit.  43,44;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1441 ;  the  result  was,  as  Scaccia, 
op.  cit.  §  2  Gloss.  7,  68  (cited  Debray,  loc.  cit.),  says,  "  Etsi  ex  formula  litterarum 
cambii  nulla  appareat  promissio  seu  obligatio  de  solvendo  illi,  qui  est  appositus 
solutioni,  tamen  subintelligitur  quod  haec  promissio  fuerit  facta  numeranti  pecuniae 
.  .  .  nam  si  ex  istis  litteris  non  resultaret  contractus  cum  promissione  et  obligatione, 
accipiens  cambio  non  posset  adstringi  ad  solutionem." 

2  Huvelin,  Travaux  re'cents,  etc.,  11-13  :  "  C'est,  en  effet,  le  systeme  que  de>agent 
les  postglossateurs.  Balde,  chez  qui  nous  en  trouvons  l'expression  la  plus  complete, 
insiste  sur  cette  idee  que  le  fait  de  remettre  au  preneur  une  lettre  contenant  la 
mention  de  valeur fournie  vaut  pour  ce  preneur  promesse  de  payer." 


138  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

(b)  The  relations  of  drawer  and  drawee. — Originally  the 
drawee  was,  in  most  cases,  either  the  principal  or  the  partner  of 
the  drawer.  He  must  pay  because  he  is  bound  by  the  contract 
of  agency  or  partnership  to  obey  the  instructions  of  the  drawer.1 
But  later  this  kind  of  relationship  did  not  necessarily  exist  between 
them.  How,  then,  could  his  liability  be  explained?  Professor 
Huvelin  thinks  that  it  came  to  be  based  on  the  idea  that  the 
drawer  has  put  the  drawee  in  funds  for  this  purpose,  that  in  sub- 
stance there  is  a  contract  of  commenda  between  them,  which  bound 
the  drawee  to  pay.2  If  he  could  show  that  he  had  not  been  thus 
put  in  funds  he  was  not  liable,  even  though  he  had  accepted  the 
bill.3 

(c)  The  relations  of  the  acceptor  and  the  payee. — By  accepting 
the  bill 4  the  drawee  recognizes  that  he  is  bound  to  obey  the  in- 
structions of  the  drawer.  In  the  course  of  the  fifteenth  century 
it  was  recognized  that,  unless  he  entered  a  protest  immediately, 
he  would  be  held  to  have  accepted ; 5  but  in  later  law  acceptance 
became  so  much  the  rule  that  it  was  left  to  the  payee  to  make 
this  protest  in  case  of  non-acceptance  or  non-payment.6  In  earlier 
days  this  acceptance  amounted  to  a  recognition  of  the  contract  of 
agency  or  partnership  existing  between  drawer  and  acceptor ;  and, 
in  later  days,  to  an  admission  that  he  had  property  of  the  drawer, 
with  which  he  must  deal  according  to  the  drawer's  instructions.7 
But  this  does  not  give  the  payee  any  right  to  enforce  that  contract. 
He  is  a  stranger  to  the  contract  between  drawer  and  acceptor. 
How  then  can  he  enforce  his  rights  ?  To  explain  this  we  must 
introduce  ideas  other  than  those  based  upon  the  Roman  law  of 

1  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  14,  "  Jusqu'au  xive  siecle  il  en  est  ainsi,  et,  lorsqu'un  tire"  ne 
paie  pas,  la  raison  qu'il  allegue  est  toujours  et  uniquement  qu'il  n'est  pas  socius  du 
tireur." 

2  Ibid  14,  15  :  "  Le  tireur  qui  fournit  provision  au  tire  le  constitue  originairement 
son  commendatarius.'1'' 

3  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  8.  1 :  "  An  exceptio  pecuniae  non  numerataa  possit 
opponi  contra  litteras  cambii.  Respondeo  affirmative  quod  potest  opponi "  ;  as 
Brissaud  says,  op.  cit.  ii  1441,  "  Par  1 'acceptation,  sans  que  le  tireur  soit  lib£re\  le 
tire"  s'engage  envers  le  porteur ;  il  le  fait  plutot  au  nom  du  tireur  qu'en  sien,  ce  qui 
lui  permet  de  se  pr£valoir  (jusque  vers  le  xvie  siecle)  des  exceptions  que  le  tireur 
pouvait  opposer  au  preneur  (par  exemple,  celui-ci  ne  lui  avait  pas  fourni  de  valeurs)  "  ; 
but  we  shall  see  that  when  Scaccia  wrote  the  broad  principle  which  he  lays  down  was 
limited  by  some  very  wide  exceptions,  below  143. 

4  This  acceptance  could  be  made  verbally,  or  per  retentionem  litter  arum,  or  in 
writing,  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  21 ;  and  that  acceptance  could  take  these  three  forms  as 
late  as  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century  is  clear  from  Marquardus,  op.  cit.  ii. 
12,  76. 

5  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1441 ;  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  15,  16. 

6  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  7,  Gloss.  2.  12  :  "  Quaero  quid  sit  redire  litteras  cum  protesta- 
tione.  Respondeo :  redire  litteras  cum  protestatione  dicimus  quando  mandatarius 
debitoris  litterarum  cambii  non  acceptat,  seu  non  solvit  litteras,  et  mandatarius 
creditoris  idcirco  protestatur  contra  debitorem  de  interesse,  damnis  et  expensis  " ; 
as  early  as  1448  there  is  an  instance  at  Avignon  of  the  payee  making  the  protest, 
see  the  case  of  Spinula  v.  Camby,  Jenks,  Essays,  A.  A.L.H.  iii  57. 

7  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  16,  17. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         139 

obligations.  The  drawer  has  received  money — property — from  the 
person  who  wishes  to  transmit  the  money.  This  money  the  drawer 
wishes  to  hand  to  the  payee,  and  puts  the  drawee  in  funds  for  this 
purpose.  If  the  drawee,  who  has  admitted  this  liability  by  accept- 
ing, does  not  fulfil  it,  he  is  in  effect  keeping  property  which 
belongs  to  the  payee.  The  payee  can  sue  the  acceptor  to  recover 
what  is  in  effect  his  property.1 

(d)  The  relations  of  the  payee  and  the  drawer. — From  an  early 
period  it  was  recognized  that,  if  the  acceptor  did  not  pay,  there 
was  a  recourse  by  the  payee  against  the  drawer.2  But  at  first 
sight  it  would  seem  difficult  to  justify  this  on  principle.  How 
could  a  third  party,  the  payee,  take  advantage  of  a  failure  by  the 
acceptor  to  fulfil  his  duty  to  the  drawer?  The  letter  by  itself  did 
not  prove  that  the  drawer  had  received  money  from  a  third  person 
to  pay  over  to  the  given  payee.3  Logically  this  was  so ;  but 
commercial  convenience  made  it  necessary  to  depart  from  strictly 
logical  principles.  Jurists  of  the  thirteenth  and  fourteenth  cen- 
turies, with  an  eye  to  the  needs  of  the  merchants,  laid  it  down  that 
the  intention  of  the  parties  must  be  regarded ;  and,  it  was  said, 
that  the  intention  of  the  parties  was  shown  by  the  fact  that  this 
letter  was  sent,  not  to  the  person  who  was  required  to  make  the 
payment  requested  by  it,  but  to  the  person  who  had  given  value.4 
This,  it  was  said,  showed  that  the  sender  of  the  letter  (the  drawer) 
had  in  effect  promised  to  pay  the  man  who  had  given  value,  and 
that  therefore  he  could  sue  on  this  promise  if  he  were  not  paid  by 
the  acceptor.5  But,  it  will  be  said,  this  gives  no  rights  to  the  payee. 
It  only  gives  rights  to  the  man  who  has  furnished  value  to  the 
drawer.  The  answer  is,  that  in  some  cases  the  man  who  gave  the 
value  was  simply  the  agent  of  the  payee ;  and  that  in  other  cases 

1  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  17 :  "  En  r^alite,  le  tireur  se  comporte  vis-a-vis  de  la  provision 
comme  s'il  avait  sur  les  especes  qui  la  representent  un  droit  de  proprtete"  et  non 
pas  comme  s'il  en  6tait  creancier.  Le  tire  qui  a  recu  provision  apparait  a  plus 
d'un  ggard  comme  un  detenteur  d'une  valeur  d'autrui  .  .  .  L'idee  de  vente,  qui  est 
l'id£e  fondamentale  du  change  manuel,  persiste  dans  le  change  tir£.  Seulement  il 
y  a  la  une  conception  tres  diff^rente  de  la  conception  romaine,  puisqu'il  s'agit 
d'une  vente  qui  n'est  pas  purement  productive  d'obligations,  mais  qui  transfere  un 
droit  de  propriete  sur  des  especes  non  encore  individualisees " ;  the  right  of  the 
payee  to  sue  was  still  a  question  discussed  when  Scaccia  wrote — some  regarded  him 
as  merely  adjectus  solutionis  see  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  7,  66-S0;  Scaccia  favours  his  right 
to  sue  and  one  of  his  grounds  is  exactly  that  taken  by  Prof.  Huvelin,  "  Quia  adiectus 
solutioni  litterarum  cambii  eo  animo,  ut  illi  iure  dominii  sit  donatum,  seu  cessum, 
vel  alio  nomine,  et  titulo  in  eo  translatum  ius,  et  actio  cambii,  potest  agere  eo  iure, 
et  quo  iura  cambii  sunt  in  eo  translata,"  loc.  cit.  71. 

2  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  5.  322  :  "  Respondeo,  Debitorem  qui  litteras  fecit  non 
esse  liberatum  .  .  .  nisi  ipsae  litterae  sint  realiter  solutae  secundum  eandem 
mercatorum  Genuensium  consuetudinem,  et  quod  faciens  litteras  cambii  sit  obli- 
gatus  restituere  pecuniam  cum  apparaverit  eius  litteras  vel  non  esse  acceptas,  vel 
non  esse  completas  ...  Si  cambium  solvendum  non  acceptatur  vel  non  solvatur, 
teneatur  creditor  " ;  cp.  Marquardu?,  De  iure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum  ii  12, 
53.  55- 

3  Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  12.  4Ibid.  5  Ibid. 


140  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

(where,  e.g.,  the  man  who  gave  value  was  the  debtor  of  the 
payee)  the  lawyers  agreed  that  this  right  of  recourse  must  belong 
to  the  dominus  negotii — to  the  man,  that  is,  for  whose  sake  this 
contract  of  cambium  had  been  entered  into.1 

In  this  way  the  bill  of  exchange  developed  at  the  close  of  the 
mediaeval  period  into  a  contract  of  a  very  special  kind.  But  as 
yet  it  possessed  none  of  the  characteristics  of  a  negotiable  instru- 
ment. Thus  (i)  even  if  the  payee  had  an  independent  right  to 
enforce  the  contract,  that  right  was  no  more  and  no  less  assignable 
by  the  payee  than  any  ordinary  contract.2  (ii)  We  have  seen  that 
the  rights  of  the  payee  depended  upon  the  fact  that  value  had  been 
given  by  the  person  who  wished  to  remit  the  money  to  the  drawer, 
and  that  this  value  had  been  passed  over  to  the  drawee  for  the 
benefit  of  the  payee.  It  followed  that  if  the  drawer  had  never 
received  this  value  he  could  not  have  passed  it  to  the  drawee  ;  and 
that  the  drawee,  even  if  he  had  accepted,  could  plead  this  fact 
as  a  defence  to  any  action  by  the  payee.3  (iii)  Similarly  the  ac- 
ceptor could  urge  any  other  defence  against  the  payee  which  could 
have  been  urged  by  the  drawer.4  How  then  did  the  bill  of  ex- 
change acquire  its  negotiable  characteristics  ? 

(iii)  The  development  of  the  negotiable  character  of  the  bill  of 
exchange. 

We  have  seen  that  there  are  three  main  characteristics 
of  negotiability — assignability ;  presumption  of  value  received,  or, 
in  English  law,  consideration  ;  and  the  acquisition  of  a  good  title  by 
a  bona-fide  holder  for  value,  irrespective  of  any  defects  in  or  want 
of  title  on  the  part  of  his  assignor.  We  must  therefore  examine 
this  question  under  these  three  heads. 

(i)  The  manner  in  which  the  bill  of  exchange  became  assign- 
able is  connected  (a)  with  the  application  to  the  bill  of  exchange 
of  the  clause  directing  payment  to  be  made  to  a  payee  or  to  any 
one  to  whom  he  might  order  payment  to  be  made  on  his  account ; 
and  (b)  with  the  practice  and  effect  of  indorsement. 

1  Scaccia,  op.  cit.  §  2,  Gloss.  7.  70 :  "  In  [litteris]  cambii  quae  vocant  ex  reditu 
nundinarum,  ut  plurimum  ii,  quibus  nominatim  in  litteris  cambii  fieri  debet 
solutio,  sunt  veri  domini  pecuniarum  et  cambii,  quare  dans  tunc  cambio  est  simplex 
minister,  et  adiectus  solutioni  est  dominus " ;  as  Huvelin  says,  op.  cit.  13,  "  II 
convient,  nous  disent  Balde  et  Scaccia,  d'appr^cier,  d'apres  la  qualite"  des  personnes 
et  les  circonstances,  qui  est  le  dominus  negotii.  Jusqu'a  preuve  contraire,  c'est  le 
pr^sentant  qui  est  repute"  l'etre." 

2  And  this  was  so  whether  it  was  made  payable  to  the  payee  or  order,  or  to  the 
payee  or  bearer,  or  to  the  bearer  simply,  above  120,  124-125  ;  cp.  the  case  of  Spinula 
v.  Camby,  cited  Jenks,  Essays,  A.  A.L.H.  iii  57-58 ;  the  plaintiff  was  non-suited  as  the 
action  should  have  been  brought  in  the  name  of  the  assignor. 

3  Above  138  and  n.  3. 

4  "  L'acceptant  pouvait  lui  (the  payee)  opposer  toutes  les  exceptions  que  le  tireur 
aurait  pu  faire  valoir  lui-meme  contre  l'ex^cution  du  constitut  (p.  ex.  exception  non 
numerate?  pecunia).  II  en  fut  effectivement  ainsi  jusque  vers  le  xvie  siecle,"  Huvelin, 
op.  cit.  20. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         141 

(a)  We  have  seen  that  an  instrument  made  payable  to  a 
creditor,  or  to  any  one  to  whom  he  might  order  it  to  be  paid,  pre- 
vented the  debtor  from  raising  any  objection  to  being  asked  to 
pay  to  the  agent  of  the  creditor  who  produced  the  document. 
But  we  have  seen  that  the  payee  designated  by  this  order  must 
be  in  a  position  to  prove,  either  that  the  creditor  had  appointed 
him  his  agent,  or  that  he  had  ceded  to  him  his  right  to  receive 
the  debt.  This  burden  of  proof  was  gradually  lightened  by  the 
practice  of  indorsement,  and  by  the  legal  effects  which  were  attri- 
buted to  it 

(J?)  The  word  "  indorse  "  means  literally  to  place  on  the  back 
(sur  dos)  of.  Thus  the  purchaser  of  land  indorsed  on  the  back  of 
the  charter  of  feoffment  the  fact  that  the  lord  had  made  livery  of 
seisin  to  him.  A  receipt  was  indorsed  on  the  back  of  the  obliga- 
tion by  a  creditor  to  whom  a  debtor  had  paid  the  sum  due  under 
the  obligation.1  In  Italy,  in  the  latter  half  of  the  sixteenth  cen- 
tury, the  practice  sprang  up  of  indorsing  upon  bills  of  exchange, 
and  later  upon  some  of  the  older  instruments  made  payable  to  a 
payee  or  order,  the  order  that  payment  should  be  made  to  X,  the 
agent  of  the  payee.  The  production  of  a  bill  with  this  order  in- 
dorsed upon  it  created  a  presumption  that  the  payee  had  handed 
it  to  X,  the  indorsee,  and  had  authorized  him  to  sue  upon  it.  It 
thus  dispensed  with  the  necessity  of  proving  a  special  authority 
given  by  the  payee  to  X  to  act  as  his  agent2  But  the  order  so 
indorsed  merely  operated  as  an  authority  to  X,  in  whose  favour 
the  order  was  given,  to  act  as  the  payee's  agent.  The  form  of  the 
clause  to  order  prevented,  as  Brunner  has  pointed  out,3  any  further 
transmission.  The  debtor  has  only  promised  to  pay  the  payee 
or  any  person  in  whose  favour  the  payee  has  given  his  order. 
There  is  therefore  no  promise  to  pay  the  person  in  whose  favour, 
not  the  payee,  but  the  indorsee  has  given  his  order.  Such  a 
person  is  the  agent,  not  of  the  payee,  but  of  the  payee's  agent — 
delegatus  non  potest  delegare. 

So  far,  therefore,  the  bill  of  exchange  has  only  attained  a  very 
limited  degree  of  assignability.  It  can  be  indorsed  and  delivered 
once,  but  that  is  all.  The  questions  then  arise:  When  did  it 
become  completely  assignable  by  means  of  repeated  indorsements 
and  deliveries?  What  was  the  legal  reasoning  by  which  this 
change  was  effected  ?  What  was  the  legal  position  of  the  various 
indorsees  inter  se  ? 

There  is  evidence  that  the  Italian  merchants  were  attempting 

1  Brunner,  Les  litres  au  porteur  francais  au  moyen  age,  N.R.H.  x,  174,  175. 

2  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1439,  1440 :  "  L'endorsement!  dispensa  de  produire  une 
procuration  sp^ciale,  puisqu'il  constituait  un  vrai  mandat  £crit  au  dos  du  titre"  ; 
Debray,  These  de  la  clause  a  ordre,  42,  46,  47. 

3  N.R.H.  x  176-177  ;  Debray,  op.  cit.  47. 


142  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

to  make  bills  of  exchange  completely  assignable  by  repeated  in- 
dorsements as  early  as  1560.  The  practice  was  alluded  to  in  a 
law  passed  at  Venice  in  1593  ;  and  it  was  forbidden  at  Naples  in 
1607  and  1617.1  Neither  the  treatises  of  Scaccia  (16 18)  nor  of 
Rafael  de  Turri  (1641)  allude  to  the  practiced  But  the  treatise  of 
Marquardus 3  shows  that  it  was  recognized  in  northern  Europe  by 
the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century ;  and  the  treatise  of 
Ansuldus  (1689)  shows  that  it  was  generally  recognized  in  Italy  in 
the  latter  part  of  the  same  century.4  In  France  it  was  recog- 
nized before  the  middle  of  the  same  century  ;  and  it  was  regulated 
by  the  Ordonnance  of  1673. 5 

The  legal  reasoning  by  which  this  change  was  effected  appears 
to  have  turned  upon  a  different  construction  which  was  placed 
upon  the  effect  of  the  order.  So  long  as  the  person  in  whose 
favour  the  order  was  given,  was  obliged  to  prove  that  he  was  the 
agent  of  the  payee  by  special  act  of  procuration  constituting  him 
agent,  either  in  rem  suam  or  in  rem  alienam,  the  representative 
character  of  the  indorsee  was  emphasized.  But  when  this  special 
act  of  procuration  was  dispensed  with,  and  the  indorsement  of  the 
order  was  accepted  as  sufficient,  the  representative  character  of 
the  indorsee  became  less  prominent.6  It  came  to  be  allowed  that 
the  indorsee,  though  a  procurator,  was  a  procurator,  not  in  rem 
alienam  but  in  rem  suam.  In  effect,  therefore,  he  became  the 
actual  transferee  entitled  to  collect  the  debt  on  his  own  account. 
It  followed  that  he  could  in  a  similar  way  appoint  another 
procurator  in  rem  suam,  and  so  on  indefinitely.7     Thus  the  as- 

1  Debray,  op.  cit.  47.  2  Ibid. 

3De  Jure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum,  ii  15,  7-10. 

4  De  Commercio  et  Mercatura,  Disc.  II.  31 ;  the  case  cited  shows  several  indorse- 
ments. 

8  Debray,  op.  cit.  50,  says  of  this  rule,  "  Si  elle  ne  naquit  pas  en  France,  elle  y 
prit  vite  racine,  et  plus  facilement  que  dans  d'autres  pays.  Tandis  qu'a  Venice,  en 
Allemagne,  a  Piedmont,  a  Naples,  aux  foires  de  Noue,  la  multiplicity  des  endossements 
demeura  longtemps  interdite,  l'ordonnance  de  1673  ne  songea  meme  pas  a  en  contester 
la  validity." 

6  Ibid  47,  48.  When  Straccha  wrote  (De  Adiecto  Pt.  4,  8,  9,  Tractatus  Juris, 
vi  Pt.  I,  400b)  a  person  who  produced  an  instrument,  which  permitted  payment 
ei  qui  exhibuerit,  was  presumed  to  be  agent,  and  admitted  to  sue  absque  cautione  de 
rato ;  this  perhaps  marks  the  beginning  of  the  process  which,  by  insisting  less  strongly 
on  the  representative  character  of  the  holder,  began  to  give  him  the  more  independent 
position  assigned  to  him  in  later  law ;  thus  Marquardus,  op.  cit.  ii  15,  18,  can  say, 
"  Nos  autem  de  delegatione  per  assignationem,  transportationem,  seu  inductionem,  ut 
mercatores  loquuntur,  facta ;  quo  in  passu  delegans  seu  transcribens  cambium  delegato 
acceptante  ulla  retractatione  mandati  aut  alio  quovis  modo  praediudicari  non  potest." 

7  "  Or  pourquoi  le  procurator  in  rem  suam  ne  pourrait-il  transferer  lui-  meme  le 
droit  dont  il  a  6t6  investi  et  par  le  meme  mode  ?  II  peut,  cela  n'est  pas  douteux, 
constituer  un  tiers  cessionnaire  au  moyen  d'une  procuratio ;  mais  puisque  l'ordre  ici 
remplace  la  procuratio,  l'insertion  dans  l'endossement  de  la  clause  a  ordre  ya  produire 
le  meme  effet  que  dans  la  lettre  elle-meme;  le  tiers  va  se  trouver  constitu^,  par  un 
second  endossement,  procurator  in  rem  suam,  sans  qu'il  soit  besoin  de  procuration 
sp£ciale  pour  ce  second  endossement  pas  plus  que  pour  le  premier,"  Debray, 
op.  cit.  48. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         143 

signability,  formerly  allowed  to  the  older  instruments  made 
payable  to  a  creditor  or  his  nominee,  was  restored.  As  M.  Debray 
has  pointed  out,  the  attainment  of  this  result,  at  the  close  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  was  due,  partly  to  a  larger  appreciation  of 
the  needs  of  the  world  of  commerce,  partly  to  the  decline  of  the 
influence  of  the  school  of  the  Renaissance  jurists.1 

The  legal  position  of  the  various  indorsees  inter  se  was  natur- 
ally dictated  by  the  legal  reasoning  which  made  several  indorse- 
ments possible.  The  principal  must  indemnify  his  agent  for  all 
expenses  to  which  the  agent  has  been  put  If,  therefore,  X,  a 
payee,  in  consideration  of  a  sum  of  money,  makes  Y  his  procurator 
in  rem  suam  by  indorsing  and  delivering  to  him  a  bill,  and  Y 
cannot  get  paid  by  the  acceptor,  X  must  indemnify  him  ;  and  if 
Y  indorses  to  Z,  the  same  principle  will  apply  as  between  Y 
and  Z.2 

(ii)  The  presumption  that  the  acceptor  of  a  bill  had  received 
value  for  it  was  gradually  admitted.  We  have  seen  that  Scaccia 
laid  it  down  that  the  acceptor  could  plead  the  exceptio  pecunice  non 
numerates  ; 3  but  he  accompanies  this  admission  with  many  excep- 
tions and  limitations.  Thus  he  admits  that  if  the  letter  contained 
the  clause  "  for  value  received,"  the  defence  could  not  be  pleaded.4 
As  this  was,  and  is,  the  general  form  of  bills  of  exchange,  it  was 
not  difficult  to  arrive  at  the  rule  laid  down  by  the  French  lawyers 
that  "  l'acceptation  suppose  la  provision,"  5  and  by  our  modern 
Bills  of  Exchange  Act  that  "  every  party  whose  signature  appears 
on  a  bill  is  prima  facie  deemed  to  have  become  a  party  thereto  for 
value."  « 

(iii)  It  was  not  difficult  to  enlarge  this  presumption.  If  con- 
sideration is   presumed,  why   not   presume   that   other  necessary 

1  Op.  cit.  50,  "  II  n'existait  plus  de  jurisconsultes  comme  Dumoulin  ou  Charondas 
dont  l'esprit  d'analyse  put  decomposer  les  elements  de  la  clause  a  ordre  et  en  faire  une 
construction  juridique  en  disaccord  avec  les  besoins  de  la  pratique  " ;  cp.  Huvelin, 
Travaux  recents,  etc.,  16,  17,  "  Or  Ton  n'a  pas  assez  remarque"  combien  Pemploi  de  la 
terminologie  et  des  conceptions  romaines  s'applique  mal  en  nos  matieres,  combien  il 
fausse  les  resultats  auxquels  on  aboutit,  et  combien  l'intervention  des  postglossateurs 
et  des  jurisconsultes  posterieurs  eleves  a  l'ecole  de  Justinien  a  rendu  plus  difficile  la 
doctrine  de  notre  institution  "  ;  for  this  school  see  vol.  iv.  225-228. 

2  Ansaldus,  op.  cit.  Disc.  II.  17  "  lam  enim  diximus  et  probavimus  quod  girata 
seu  cessio  non  sit  contractus  mercati  sed  mandati  " ;  ibid  30  ["  Girata  litterae  cambii] 
aequipollere  pecuniae  numeratae,  sed  dum  modo  subsequatur  solutio,  alias  datur  regressus 
adversus  trahentem  seu  scribentem." 

3  Above  138  n.  3. 

4  Op.  cit.  §  2  Gloss.  8,  5,  6  "  Limita  primo  eandem  regulam,  ut  non  procedat, 
quando  campsarius,  id  est  debitor,  confessus  esset  in  litteris  cambii  numerationem 
pecuniae.  .  .  .  Declara,  explicando  uberius  hanc  limitationem,  ut  in  civitate  Genue  ex 
communi  mercatorum  observantia  campsarius  dicatur  confessus  numerationem  pecuniae 
in  litteris  cambii,  quando  in  litteris  sunt  opposita  ilia  verba,  per  la  valuta  havauta  di 
contanti." 

5  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1441 ;  Huvelin,  Travaux  recents,  etc.,  20. 
*45  and  46  Victoria  c  61,  s.  30,  1. 


144  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

elements  of  the  validity  of  the  bill  are  present?  It  would  seem 
that  this  presumption  was  made  in  France  in  the  seventeenth 
century  ;  and  it  followed  that  defences  good  against  a  payee  were 
not  necessarily  good  against  an  indorsee.1  But  could  this  pre- 
sumption omnia  rite  acta  be  rebutted?  It  seems  to  have  been 
settled  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century  that  it  could 
not,  if  the  person  entitled  under  the  bill  took  in  good  faith  ;  and 
good  faith  was  always  presumed.2  This  conclusion  seems  to  have 
been  arrived  at  by  basing  the  acceptor's  liability  to  the  payee  on 
quite  a  different  ground  from  that  taken  by  the  older  law.  It  was 
thought  that,  by  accepting,  he  personally  promised  to  pay  to  the 
payee  or  anyone  who  appeared  as  indorsee.  His  contract  was 
therefore  with  the  indorsee  who  appeared  with  the  bill.3  This 
liability  could  not  be  affected  by  any  equities  existing  as  against 
any  one  else,  because  to  the  contract  between  the  acceptor  and  the 
ultimate  indorsee  any  one  else  was  a  stranger.4 

Thus  the  bill  of  exchange  gained,  in  the  middle  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  many  of  the  negotiable  characteristics  which  the 
older  instruments  payable  to  order  or  bearer  had  lost  in  the 
sixteenth  century.  It  was  not  difficult,  in  those  countries  in  which 
the  bearer  of  these  instruments  still  retained  an  independent  right 
of  action,  and  later  in  all  countries  in  which  his  independent  posi- 
tion had  come  to  be  recognized,  to  make  these  bills  also  payable 
to  bearer.  Under  the  influence  of  a  school  of  lawyers  less 
enslaved  to  the  classical  texts  than  the  Renaissance  jurists,  and 
more  alive  to  the  interests  of  commerce,5  the  bill  of  exchange  was 
permitted  to  supply  the  want  caused  by  the  disappearance  of  the 
negotiable  character  of  the  older  instruments.  And  thus,  though 
much  younger  than  these  instruments,  though  originally  mere 
letters  without  any  legal  significance,  they  have  become  the  type  and 

1  Debray,  op.  cit.  57,  and  authorities  there  cited ;  cp.  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii 
1441-1442.    ■ 

2  See  Brunner,  op.  cit.  143-144. 

3Ansaldus.  op.  cit.  Disc.  I.  10,  "Tunc  per  eandem  acceptationem  censetur 
acceptans  sese  fecisse  debitorem  ex  causa  propria,  vel  tamquam  fideiussorem  scribentis, 
ut  dicunt  in  ratione  decidendi  Authoritates  mox  recensitae  "  ;  ibid  Disc.  IV.  3  "  Qui 
huiusmodi  litteras  acceptando  nulla  sese  valent  exceptione  tueri,  sed  compelluntur 
solvere,  ac  si  per  solemnem  stipulationem  sese  soluturos  prsefixo  tempore  promisissent 
et  obligassent." 

4  Ibid  Disc.  II.  37-39  "  Recepta  propositio,  quod  exceptio,  quae  obstat  cedenti 
vel  giranti  non  obstat  cessionario  vel  giratario,  de  qua  in  terminis  mandatarii 
acceptantis  mandatum  de  solvendo  alicui  tertio,  quod  non  possit  solutionem  denegare 
giratario,  non  solum  si  non  sit  debitor,  sed  etiam  si  sit  creditor  girantis  .  .  .  De  eo, 
qui  cum  fecisset  cedulam,  seu,  ut  dicitur,  Pagaro,  quod  non  possit  iste  recusare  solu- 
tionem giratario,  quantumvis  fuisset  creditor  illius,  qui  receperat,  et  respective 
giraverat  idem  Pagaro,  dum  modo  giratarius  foveat  causam  onerosam,  et  non  repre- 
sentet  tanquam  simpliciter  adiectus  personam  girantis  " ;  cp.  ibid  Disc.  LXXII  5 
"  Exceptio,  quae  competeret  contra  excommunicatum  cedentem,  obiici  non  valeat 
cessionario,  veluti  vitium  mere  personale." 

5  Above  143  and  n.  1. 


ORIGINS  AND  DEVELOPMENT         145 

model  of  the  negotiable  instruments  known  to  our  modern  law  ; 
and,  as  Brissaud  has  pointed  out,  they  have  in  consequence  come 
to  perform  a  new  function  in  the  modern  world  of  commerce. 
They  have  become  modes  of  payment  and  instalments  of  credit — 
a  species  of  currency,  in  fact,  among  merchants.  The  value  which 
they  represent  is  incorporated  in  them  ;  and  the  ingenious  device  of 
modern  commercial  practice  has  thus  curiously  revived  the  formal 
carta  of  the  early  mediaeval  period.1 

How  the  negotiable  characteristics  of  these  instruments  can  be 
reconciled  with  legal  principle  is  a  matter  upon  which  there  has 
been  much  speculation.2  Such  speculation  is  outside  the  sphere 
of  legal  history ;  but  I  think  that  the  history  of  their  growth 
would  seem  to  suggest  that  these  characteristics  cannot  be  ex- 
plained by  reference  to  the  principles  solely  applicable  either  to 
the  law  of  property  or  to  the  law  of  contract.  It  suggests  rather 
that  they  are  a  judicious  mixture  of  those  parts  of  the  principles 
underlying  both  these  bodies  of  law,  which  are  the  most  favourable 
to  safe,  easy,  and  rapid  circulation.  If  we  look  at  the  law  of 
property  we  see  that  there  is  no  difficulty  in  assigning  property, 
provided  that  the  assignor  has  a  good  title.  But  "  nemo  dat  quod 
non  habet. "  If  we  look  at  the  law  of  contract  we  see  that  there 
is  no  difficulty  about  the  binding  force  of  a  contract  to  convey 
another  person's  property.  The  promissor  is  obviously  bound 
personally  if  he  chooses  to  make  such  a  contract.  But  difficulties 
begin  when  we  attempt  to  assign  the  benefit  of  a  contract  The 
negotiable  instrument  avoids  both  the  proprietary  and  the  con- 
tractual difficulty  by  a  judicious  mixture  of  principles  taken  from 
both  these  branches  of  law.  It  borrows  from  the  law  of  property 
the  easy  method  of  assignment  by  means  of  an  indorsement  and 
delivery,  or  a  delivery  merely  of  the  instrument  It  borrows  from 
the  law  of  contract  the  principle  that  the  person  primarily  liable  is 
personally  bound  by  his  contract  to  pay  the  indorsee  or  bearer 
producing  the  bill  ;  and  that,  therefore,  no  defence,  which  he 
might  have  had  to  claims  by  other  persons,  and  no  question  of 
title  to   the  bill,    can  be   any   answer  to  an  indorsee  or  bearer 

1  Op.  cit.  ii  1442  :  "  Elle  ne  servit  d'abord  qu'a  eviter  un  transport  d'argent :  on 
en  fait  un  moyen  de  payement  et  un  instrument  de  credit,  une  sorte  de  monnaie  entre 
commercants ;  la  valeur  qu'elle  represente  s'incorpore  a  elle  et  la  pratique  savante  des 
temps  modernes  revient  ainsi  par  un  detour  inattendu  a  la  carta  formaliste  d'epoque 
barbare." 

2  For  some  account  of  this  discussion  see  Huvelin,  Travaux  regents,  etc.,  17-21 ; 
he  favours  the  idea  that  the  bill  of  exchange  is  primarily  a  rente  d'esjeces,  but,  as  he 
admits,  writers  of  the  seventeenth  century  regarded  it  also  as  a  cession  de  creance ;  on 
the  other  hand,  the  German  law  regards  the  thing  ceded  as  a  dette  abstracte  which  the 
acceptor  is  personally  bound  to  pay  to  the  holder.  As  we  can  see  from  the  foregoing 
discussion,  both  ideas  have  played  their  part  in  fashioning  the  modern  law ;  for  what 
we  may  call  the  proprietary  idea  see  above  142-143  ;  for  what  we  may  call  the  con- 
tractual idea  see  above  143-144. 

VOL.  VIII. — 10 


146  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

producing  the  bill,  who  has  acquired  it  in  good  faith  and  for 
value.  In  addition,  it  borrows  from  mercantile  custom  the  prin- 
ciple that,  normally,  good  faith  and  value  will  be  presumed. 

By  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  continental  lawyers  had 
substantially  come  to  these  conclusions.  We  shall  now  see  that 
their  development  in  England  closely  followed  their  development 
on  the  Continent. 


Introduction  into  England  and  development  by  the  Common  Law 

The  negotiable  instrument  came  to  England  from  the  Continent ; 
and  its  adventures  in  England  present  some  analogies  to  its 
adventures  in  the  countries  from  whence  it  came.  Therefore, 
although  its  history  in  England  is  in  some  respects  unique,  neither 
that  history  nor  the  law  resulting  therefrom,  can  be  understood 
without  the  help  of  the  light  thrown  upon  them  by  continental 
analogies. 

There  are  some  indications  that  instruments  payable  to  a  creditor 
or  his  nominee,  and  perhaps  instruments  payable  to  a  creditor  or 
bearer,  were  known  in  mediaeval  England ; !  and  possibly  these 
instruments  possessed  certain  negotiable  characteristics.  But  cases 
turning  upon  them  did  not  come  before  the  common-law  courts ; 
and  there  is  reason  to  think  that,  if  they  had  done  so,  these  negoti- 
able characteristics  would  have  been  as  strange  to  the  common  law 
as  they  were  to  the  civil  law.2  No  doubt  the  bill  of  exchange 
was  well  enough  known  to  the  mercantile  world ;  and  the  cases 
from  the  Mayor's  Court  in  London,  which  have  been  already  cited, 
show  that  it  was  well  enough  known  to  the  English  merchants.3 
But  it  is  not  till  the  sixteenth  century  that  there  are  any  indications 
that  its  existence  had  become  known  to  English  lawyers.  In  the 
course  of  the  following  century  it  was  received  into  English  law, 
and  recognized  as  possessing  the  same  negotiable  characteristics 
that  it  had  acquired  abroad.  It  was  therefore  in  connexion  with 
the  bill  of  exchange  that  the  common  law  first  became  acquainted 
with  negotiability. 

During  the  seventeenth  century  some  lawyers  were  inclined  to 
follow  mercantile  usage,  and  to  attribute  this  quality  of  negotia- 
bility to  certain  other  bills  or  notes,  containing  promises  to  pay 
money  to  a  creditor  or  order  or  to  a  creditor  or  bearer.  But  in  the 
last  years  of  that  century  the  courts,  under  the  influence  of  Holt, 
C.J.,  decided  that  negotiability  was  the  peculiar  property  of  the 
bill  of  exchange.     This  led  to  such  serious  inconvenience  that,  at 

1  Vol.  i  543;  vol.  v  114;  above  116,  130-131. 

2  Below  147.  3  Above.  116,  130-131. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        147 

the  end  of  this  period,  the  Legislature  declared  that  these  promissory 
notes  were  and  always  had  been  negotiable. 

This  summary  of  the  early  history  of  negotiable  instruments  in 
England  indicates  the  main  lines  of  development.  I  shall  relate 
that  history  under  the  following  heads :  (i)  the  older  instruments 
payable  to  a  creditor  or  his  nominee,  or  to  a  creditor  or  bearer  ; 
(2)  the  bill  of  exchange ;  and  (3)  the  promissory  note. 

(1)  The  older  instruments  payable  to  a  creditor  or  his  nominee 
or  to  a  creditor  or  bearer. 

We  have  seen  that  there  are  a  few  slight  indications  that  the 
courts  of  the  mediaeval  English  fairs  knew  of  these  older  instru- 
ments.1 But,  in  the  printed  collections  of  these  cases,  there  is  only 
one  case  in  which  such  an  instrument  is  made  payable  to  bearer ; 
and  in  that  case  it  was  the  party  to  whom  it  was  made  payable, 
and  not  the  bearer,  who  sued  upon  it2  In  other  cases  these 
instruments  were  made  payable  to  the  certo  at  tomato  or  nuncio 
producing  them.3  Similarly,  we  get  in  Madox's  collection  a 
certain  number  of  instruments  in  which  there  is  a  promise  to  pay 
to  a  creditor  or  to  his  "certain  attorney";4  and  in  two  of  these 
precedents  the  money  is  to  be  paid  to  the  certain  attorney 
"producing  the  instrument"5  The  inference  would  seem  to  be 
that  the  assignable  instruments,  which  we  find  on  the  Continent, 
were  unknown  to  or  ignored  by  the  mediaeval  common  law.  No 
doubt,  as  the  power  to  appoint  an  attorney  came  to  be  generally 
permitted,  the  creditor  could  enforce  his  right  through  his  attorney 
duly  appointed — probably  whether  this  fact  were  mentioned  in 
the  instrument  or  not.6  But,  from  the  fact  that  the  common  law 
never  recognized  the  assignability  of  any  chose  in  action,  we  may 
infer  that  it  was  only  the  creditor  himself  or  his  duly  appointed 
attorney  who  could  enforce  them."  Therefore  if  such  instruments 
had  been  known  to  the  mediaeval  common  lawyers,  they  would 
probably  have  been  treated  by  them  much  in  the  same  way  as  they 
were  treated  by  the  civilians  abroad.8 

It  is  probable,  however,  that  these  instruments  were  well  enough 
known  to  those  few  English  merchants  who  were  engaged  in 
foreign  trade.  At  any  rate,  the  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty 
show  us  that,  from  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century,  they 

1  Vol.  i  543  ;  vol.  v  114  ;  above  116. 

2  Select  Pleas  in  Manorial  Courts  (S.S.)  152.  3  Above  116. 
*Formulare  Anglicanum,  nos.  641,  642,  645,  647,  648,  649,  651. 

5  Ibid  nos.  643  and  653  ;  in  the  latter  tie  creditor  is  Robert  Rede,  Justice  of  the 
bench,  and  the  payment  is  to  be  made  "  Roberto  aut  suo  certo  attornato  hoc  scriptum 
ostendenti,  haeredibus  executoribus  suis  "  ;  it  is  dated  March  8,  1501 ;  and  the  money 
is  stated  to  have  been  lent  '» pro  mercandisis  in  Stapula  Westmonasterii  emptis." 

6  Vol.  ii  316-317.  "  Vol.  vii.  533,  534-537.  s  Above  121-125. 


148  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

were  an  ordinary  part  of  the  machinery  of  commerce.  Thus  in 
1533  we  find  the  following  document  :x  "Be  it  known  to  all  men 
that  I  Thomas  Thorne  haberdasher  of  London  have  taken  up  by 
exchange  of  Thomas  Fuller  merchaunt  of  the  staple  of  Calais  the 
sum  of  lxH  sterling,  the  which  sum  of  three  skore  pounds  sterling 
to  be  payd  to  the  said  Thomas  Fuller  or  to  the  brynger  of  thys  byll  in 
manner  and  forme  foloynge  ...  to  the  whiche  payments  well  and 
trewly  to  be  payd  to  the  said  Thomas  Fuller  or  to  the  brynger  hereof 
...  I  the  said  Thomas  Thorne  bynd  me  myne  ayres  executors  and 
assignes  and  all  my  goods."  The  bill  is  signed  and  sealed  by  the 
maker.  In  1536  we  have  a  similar  bill  drawn  in  a  set  of  three, 
and  promising  to  pay  to  the  creditor  or  his  assigns.  It  runs  as 
follows : 2  "Be  yt  knowne  unto  all  men  by  this  my  second  byll 
not  beyng  payd  my  fyrst  nor  thyrd  I  William  Browne  merchaunt 
of  Tynbe  .  .  .  knowlage  that  I  owe  unto  you  Thomas  Gale  haber- 
dasher of  London  xH  xs  sterling  the  which  tene  pounds  and  tene 
shillings  starling  I  promys  and  me  bynd  to  pay  unto  the  sayd 
Thomas  Galle  or  to  his  assignes."  In  1  5  3  8  3  we  have  a  combination 
of  these  clauses.  In  a  document  under  seal,  John  Stubbarde, 
citizen  and  fishmonger  of  London,  and  Peter  Kyrseeman,  merchant 
of  Bruges,  bind  themselves  to  pay  £1 3  to  John  Harryson  de  Roos, 
mariner  of  Sluys,  for  a  certain  ship  which  they  had  bought  of  him  ; 
and  this  sum  is  to  be  paid  to  "the  said  John  or  to  his  certain 
attorney  his  heirs  executors  or  assigns  or  to  the  presenter  or  bearer 
of  this  present  writing."  There  are  several  other  similar  documents 
appearing  in  the  same  records,4  all  of  which,  it  is  fairly  clear, 
correspond  to  the  instruments  payable  to  a  creditor  or  his  nominee 
or  to  a  creditor  or  bearer  which  were  in  use  on  the  Continent. 
The  question  therefore  arises — What  effect  was  given  to  them  by 
mercantile  practice  and  by  English  law  ? 

On  both  these  points  Malynes'  treatise  gives  us  some  informa- 
tion ;  and  that  information  probably  presents  both  the  practice  and 
the  law  of  the  greater  part  of  the  sixteenth  and  of  the  earlier  part 
of  the  seventeenth  centuries. 

Malynes  tells  us5  that  the  "most  usual  buying  and  selling  of 
commodities  beyond  the  seas,  in  the  course  of  traffick,  is  by  Bills 
of  Debt  or  obligations  called  Bills  Obligatory,  which  one  merchant 
giveth  unto  another  for  commodities  bought  or  sold,  which  is 
altogether  used  by  the  Merchants  Adventurers  at  Amsterdam, 
Middleborough,  Hamborough,  and  other  places."  He  gives  us  the 
following  specimens  of  the  usual  form  of  these  bills:6  "I,  A.B. 

1  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  41. 

2  Ibid  55.  3  Ibid  62,  196. 

4 Ibid  72  (1538-1539) ;  ii  68  (1538) — called  a  bill  of  exchange;  70(1549);  ibid 
7c,  71  (1554)— called  a  bill  of  exchange  ;  71  (1553) ;  72  (1557) ;  73  (1557)- 
5  Lex  Mercatoria,  71.  6  Op.  cit.  74. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT         149 

merchant  of  Amsterdam  do  acknowledge  by  these  presents  to  be 
truely  indebted  to  the  honest  CD.  English  merchant  dwelling  at 
Middleborough,  in  the  sum  of  five  hundred  pounds  currant  money 
for  merchanize,  which  is  for  commodities  received  of  him  to  my 
contentment,  which  summ  of  five  hundred  pounds  as  aforesaid  I  do 
promise  to  pay  unto  the  said  CD.  {or  the  bringer  hereof)  within  six 
months  next  after  the  date  of  these  presents :  In  witness  whereof 
I  have  subscribed  the  same  at  Amsterdam  the  10  of  July,  1622, 
Stilo  novo,  A.B. ' 

It  is  reasonably  clear  that  this  is  one  of  the  old  instruments  to 
bearer,  adapted  to  modern  commercial  conditions,  which  had  long 
been  known  on  the  Continent.  We  have  seen  that,  before  the  date 
when  Malynes  wrote,  they  had  lost  those  negotiable  qualities  which 
they  had  possessed  in  earlier  law.1  But  on  the  Continent  the 
merchants  had  invented  a  cumbersome  device  by  means  of  which 
they  could  be  made  assignable  The  creditor  and  payee  of  such  a 
bill  stipulated  with  his  debtor,  the  maker,  that  he  (the  debtor) 
would  make  the  bill  payable  to  any  person  nominated  by  himself. 
The  maker  thereupon  drew  the  bill,  leaving  the  name  of  the  payee 
blank.  The  original  creditor  then  handed  this  bill  to  a  creditor  of 
his  own  to  present  to  the  maker  thereof.  But  this  assignee  might, 
by  a  similar  method,  make  use  of  it  to  pay  a  creditor  of  his ;  and 
so  the  bill  might  pass  through  half  a  dozen  different  hands  before 
it  was  finally  presented  to  the  maker  by  the  man  who  wished  to 
have  his  name  inserted  as  payee.2  Or,  Malynes  tells  us,  the  bill 
might  be  made  payable  to  the  original  payee  or  bearer ;  "  and  so  all 
the  parties  are  bearers  thereof,  unto  whom  the  same  is  set  over  by 
a  tradition  of  it  only."3  It  should  be  observed,  however,  that  all 
depended  on  the  solvency  of  the  maker.  The  names  of  the  several 
transferees  did  not  appear  on  the  bill,  and  therefore  they  had  no 
recourse  against  each  other.4  It  was  not  till  the  clause  to  order 
and  the  practice  of  indorsement  had  been  applied  to  these  bills  that 
this  security  was  gained.5  But  it  would  seem  that,  when  Malynes 
wrote,  this  device  had  not  yet  been  applied  to  these  bills.  The 
only  bills  with  which  he  was  acquainted  were  bills  to  bearer.  In 
spite,  however,  of  this  defect,  it  is  clear  that  these  bills  of  debt 
were,  among  the  merchants,  regarded  as  a  species  of  mercantile 
currency.     The  parties  by  themselves  or  their  brokers  had  (like 

1  Above  124-125.  2  Lex  Mercatoria,  71. 

3  Ibid.  "  This,"  he  says,  "  is  called  a  rescounter  in  payment,  used  among  mer- 
chants beyond  the  seas,  and  seemeth  strange  unto  all  men  that  are  ignorant  of  this 
custom." 

*  Ibid  73— a  case  cited  to  show  that  the  practice  of  getting  the  name  of  the 
creditor's  nominee  inserted  in  the  bill  "  is  not  without  some  danger  "  to  the  nominee, 
in  case  the  debtor  turn  out  to  be  insolvent. 

5  Below  155-156. 


150  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

our  modern  bill  brokers)1  means  of  finding  out  the  commercial 
reputation  of  the  maker  of  any  bill,  which  an  intending  purchaser 
proposed  to  give  in  payment ;  and  the  holder  of  such  bills  could 
sell  these  bills  and  get  ready  money  for  them.  These  bills  are,  as 
he  says,  "as  money  paid  by  assignation."2 

The  advantages  of  this  mercantile  custom  are  eloquently  set 
forth  by  Malynes3 — "very  great  matters  are  compassed  in  the 
trade  of  Merchandize,  the  commodities  are  sooner  vented  in  all 
places,  the  custom  and  impositions  of  Princes  do  increase,  the 
poor  and  mechanical  people  are  set  on  work,  men  are  better 
assured  in  their  payments,  the  counterfeiting  of  bills  and  differences 
are  prevented  ;  the  more  commodities  there  are  sold,  the  less  ready 
money  is  transported,  and  life  is  infused  into  traffkk  and  trade  for 
the  general  good."  But  he  is  forced  to  admit  that  this  mercantile 
custom  was  wholly  unknown  to  and  legally  impossible  in  the 
common  law.  Being  choses  in  action  they  could  not  be  assigned.4 
If  they  were  drawn  up,  as  they  usually  were,  in  the  form  of  a 
contract  under  seal,  they  could  not  be  made  payable  to  bearer,  or 
altered  into  another  man's  name ;  and  letters  of  attorney  given  by 
the  payee  to  an  assignee  to  sue  in  his  (the  payee's)  name  were 
always  revocable.5  Many  lawyers  and  merchants,  he  tells  us,  had 
advocated  the  establishment  of  this  custom  in  England  by  Act  of 
Parliament ; 6  and  he  makes  the  further  suggestion  that  transfers 
should  be  indorsed  on  the  bill,  and  that  there  should  be  (as  at 
Lisbon  and  Rouen)  a  register  kept  of  all  these  bills.7     But  these 

1  Bagehot,  Lombard  Street,  285,  286. 

2"  This  custom  is  much  practised  by  the  Merchants  Adventurers  beyond  the  seas 
at  Middleborough,  Atrsterdam,  Antwerp,  Hamborough  and  other  places  where  they 
do  trade,  in  manner  following  as  we  have  noted  : — A  merchant  having  many  of  these 
bills,  which  he  hath  received  for  his  clothes  .  .  .  will  resort  unto  .  .  .  another 
merchant,  commonly  accompanied  with  a  mediator  or  broker,  to  buy  a  good  round 
quantity  of  silk  wares  .  .  .  and  having  agreed  upon  the  price  of  the  said  commodity  .  .  . 
he  makcth  the  seller  acquainted  with  what  payment  ...  he  will  give  him  in  bills  .  .  . 
Hereupon  all  such  bills  as  are  of  known  persons,  are  soon  accepted  of,  and  of  the 
unknown  persons,  either  himself  that  is  the  seller  or  the  broker,  will  enquire  of  them 
sufficiently,  and  then  likewise  accept  their  bills  in  payment";  enquiry  was  then 
usually  made  of  the  debtor  whether  he  will  meet  the  bills  (which  were  usually  made 
payable  to  bearer)  and  the  debtor  assents.  The  receiver  may  either  wait  till  the  bills 
fall  due  and  get  the  money,  or  "  buy  other  commodities  therewith  "  ;  "  nay  more,  if 
he  will  have  ready  money  for  these  bills,  he  may  sell  them  to  other  merchants  that  are 
moneyed  men  .  .  .  which  is  commodious  for  young  merchants  having  small  stocks, 
as  also  for  all  men  upon  all  occasions  ;  for  it  is  properly  as  money  paid  by  assignation," 
Lex  Mercatoria,  72-73. 

3  Ibid  73.  4  Ibid  71.  5  Ibid  73.  B  Ibid   71. 

7  "  If  there  were  a  register  kept  of  the  passing  and  transferring  of  these  bills  from 
man  to  man,  and  by  an  endorsement  thereof  also  upon  the  bill,  it  might  be  done  with 
ease,  and  the  bearer  of  it  should  be  acknowledged  thereby  to  be  a  lawful  Attorney  in 
law  ;  and  by  these  means  the  undecent  plea  of  Non  est  factum  would  be  cut  off.  And 
to  prevent  fraudulent  dealing,  if  any  bills  should  be  lost,  notice  might  be  given 
instantly  to  the  Register  (which  at  Lixborn  and  Roan  is  called  a  Prothonotary)  .  .  . 
and  the  bills  for  the  most  part  do  remain  in  the  office  at  the  disposition  of  the  last 
assign  or  assigns,"  ibid  73,  74  ;  the  keeping  of  a  register  of  bills  of  exchange  in  order 
to  prevent  the  secret  export  of  money  was  advocated  in  1621  and  1638,  S.P.  Dom. 
1619-1623,  255,  exxi  20  ;  1638-1639,  257,  ccccviii  45. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT         151 

suggestions  bore  no  fruit.  "Hitherto  things  are  not  rightly 
understood,  as  it  is  to  be  wished  it  were,  whereby  other  nations 
have  still  an  advantage."  ! 

In  England,  as  abroad,  it  was  not  till  the  modern  idea  of 
negotiability  had  come  into  the  common  law  in  the  train  of  the 
bill  of  exchange,  that  these  bills  obligatory  developed  into  negoti- 
able instruments,  and  became  the  promissory  notes  of  our  modern 
law.  To  the  advent  of  the  bill  of  exchange  in  this  country  we 
must  now  turn. 

(2)  The  bill  of  exchange. 

The  bill  of  exchange,  and  the  law  and  practice  relating  thereto, 
were  known  to  English  merchants  long  before  they  were  fully 
received  into  the  common  law.2  When,  in  the  early  part  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  the  common  law  courts  began  to  recognize 
the  validity  of  these  instruments,  they  were  already  a  developed 
institution.3  It  was  inevitable  therefore  that  the  common  law 
should  receive,  along  with  them,  the  law  which  had  grown  up 
around  them  on  the  Continent  This  reception  took  place  under 
cover  of  the  recognition  of  mercantile  custom ;  but  it  was  no 
wholesale  or  slavish  reception.  No  doubt,  both  our  system  of 
case  law,  and  the  insularity  of  the  common  lawyers,  helped  to  pre- 
vent a  reception  of  this  kind.  Foreign  writers  are  very  rarely 
cited  in  the  reports ; 4  and  foreign  doctrine  was  both  modified, 
when  modifications  were  necessary  to  suit  the  different  technical 
conceptions  of  English  law,  and  added  to,  when  new  cases  produced 
new  problems  for  solution.  This  process  was  in  full  operation 
during  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century.  It  was  naturally 
far  less  rapid  than  it  would  have  been  if  foreign  doctrine  had  been 
received  in  a  more  wholesale  manner ;  and  therefore  at  the  end 
of  this  century  English  law  was  less  detailed,  and  perhaps  less 
advanced,  than  the  law  of  many  continental  countries.  But  the 
process  had  fairly  started,  and  good  progress  had  been  made. 

The  history  of  the  bill  of  exchange  therefore  falls  under  two 
well  defined  heads  :  (i)  the  bill  of  exchange  in  mercantile  practice  ; 

1  Lex  Mercatoria,  74  ;  it  may  however  be  noted  that  a  bill  to  make  bills  of  debt 
transferable  by  indorsement  was  before  the  House  of  Lords  in  1669,  but  it  dropped 
with  the  close  of  the  session,  ibid  MSS.  Com.  8th  Rep.  App.  137 ;  and  that  in 
February  1672-1673  an  Act  for  assigning  bills  and  bonds  was  ordered  to  be  prepared 
by  the  House  of  Lords,  which  got  as  far  as  its  first  reading  in  January  1673-1674, 
Journals  of  the  House  of  Lords  xii  53S,  623  ;  Hist  MSS.  Comm.  oth  Rep.  App.  Pt. 
ii  40  no.  151 ;  a  similar  proposal  had  been  made  in  1653,  vol.  vi  418. 

2  Above  130-131.  3  Above  136-145. 

*  In  Carter  v.  Downish  (1687)  1  Shower  at  p.  128,  there  is  a  reference  in  argu- 
ment to  "all  the  book  cases  on  foreign  bills  of  exchange";  and  another  general 
reference  to  the  civil  law  in  the  argument  in  Claxton  v.  Swift  (1685)  2  Shower  at 
p.  501 ;  even  general  references  such  as  these  are  very  rare. 


152  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and  (ii)  the  recognition  and  development  of  the  bill  of  exchange  in 
English  law. 

(i)  The  bill  of  exchange  in  mercantile  practice. 

Though,  as  we  have  seen,1  documents  which  were  in  substance 
bills  of  exchange  had  made  their  appearance  in  the  Mayor's  Court 
of  London  at  the  very  beginning  of  the  thirteenth  century,  they 
do  not  make  their  appearance  in  the  central  courts  till  much  later. 
There  is  a  possible  reference  to  a  document,  which  is  something 
like  a  bill  of  exchange,  in  a  case  heard  by  the  court  of  Chancery 
between  i486  and  1500.2  But  the  earliest  specimens  of  bills  of 
exchange  are  to  be  found  in  the  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty. 
It  is  clear  from  their  form  that  they  are  exactly  similar  to  the 
bills  of  exchange  known  on  the  Continent.  The  earliest  is  a 
Latin  document  of  the  year  1540  translated  from  the  Italian,8  and 
there  are  others  of  1553, 4  1 5 54,5  I562,6and  1 563  7  in  English. 
If  we  compare  the  specimens  of  1540,  1562,  and  1563  with  the 
specimen  given  by  Malynes,  we  shall  see  that  in  England  they 
were  drawn  in  the  same  stereotyped  form  as  in  other  parts  of 
Europe.8 

The  following  is  the  form  which  Malynes9  gives  of  a  bill  of 
exchange  from  London  to  Amsterdam  : — 

1  Above  130-131. 

2  Proceedings  in  Chancery  (R.C.)  i  cxx-cxxii  ;  the  plaintiff,  Sebastian  Giglis, 
merchant  of  Venice,  alleges  that  at  the  request  of  the  defendant,  Robert  Welby,  priest, 
he  wrote  to  one  Reale,  a  merchant,  a  letter  asking  Reale  to  pay  to  Welby  £20.  Reale 
did  so,  taking  a  document  with  sureties  signed  by  Welby  for  repayment.  He  was 
unable  to  get  payment  at  common  law  because  the  document  was  not  sealed,  and 
Welby  waged  his  law.  Therefore  Reale  sued  Giglis  who  was  obliged  to  pay.  On 
these  grounds  the  Chancellor  ordered  Welby  to  pay  the  money  to  Giglis ;  this  letter, 
if  not  actually  a  bill  of  exchange,  is  certainly  reminiscent  of  the  mercantile  practice 
which  gave  rise  to  them. 

3  It  runs  as  follows:  "  Jhesus  1540,  26  die  Julii  in  London,"  cxviii  li.  xviii  s. 
monete  Flandrie  currentis. 

"  Ad  tempus  solitum  Anglice  at  usans  solvetis  pro  hac  prima  presenti  billa  cambii 
D.  Barnardo  Calvalcanti  libras  centum  et  octodecim  et  solidos  octodecim  grossorum 
in  moneta  currenti  pro  valore  recepto  a  Guidone  Cavalcanti  et  ponetis  in  computo 
V  .  .  .  orum  hie  Subscripcio  literarum  cambii  Meliadux  Spinola. 

"  Superscripcio  literarum  huiusmodi  D.  Adriano  de  Brancho  iuniori  in  Antuerpia. 

"  (In  the  margin)  Tenor  literarum  cambii  ex  Italico  idiomate  in  Latinum  trans- 
latarum,"  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  6g. 

4  Ibid  70.  5  Ibid  71.  6  Ibid  73.  7  Ibid. 

8  The  following  is  the  bill  of  1562  :  "  Laus  deo.  Andwarpe  le  4  of  September 
1562  £50  o.  o. 

"At  Usans  and  halfe  paye  by  this  my  fyrste  byll  of  exchainge  my  second  not 
beinge  paid  to  Myhell  Cruche  or  the  bringer  hereof  the  some  ffyeftey  poundes  sterlinge 
corant  mony  for  marchandyse  and  ys  for  the  valewe  receyved  here  of  John  Turner 
at  the  daye  make  good  payment  and  put  yt  to  your  accompte  by  me  Richard 
Stainffeld. 

"  Eccepted  by  me  William  Lewtie. 

"  (Endorsed)  To  Mr.  Lewteye  servant  to  Richard  Stainffyld  dd  in  London  pa," 

D  Lex  Mercatoria,  269,  270, 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT         153 

"Laus  Deo.  Adi  24  August  1622  in  London — 500  lb.  at 
34s.  6d. 

"At  usance1  pay  by  this  my  first  bill  of  exchange  to  A.B.  the 
sum  of  five  hundred  pounds  sterling  at  thirty-four  shillings  and  six 
pence  Flemish  for  every  pound  sterling  currant  money  in  merchan- 
dize for  the  value  hereof  received  by  me  of  CD.  and  put  it  to 
account  as  per  advice,  A.  Dio.  etc.  G.M." 

Then,  "on  the  backside  is  indorsed,  To  my  loving  friend, 
Master  W.  C.  merchant  in  Amsterdam,  Pa."  2 

Malynes  says3  that  the  bill  must  always  be  in  this  form — 
"You  may  not  say  in  the  bill  it  may  please  you  to  pay  or  I  pray 
you  to  pay,  although  it  were  to  your  master;  for  the  bill  of  his 
high  nature  doth  carry  with  it  a  command  .  .  .  neither  is  there 
any  witness  unto  it  nor  any  seal,  but  a  small  piece  of  paper  of 
some  two  fingers  broad :  and  the  letter  of  advice  doth  declare  for 
whose  account,  or  to  what  intent  or  purpose  the  said  money  is 
taken  up."4 

It  is  clear  from  this  specimen  that  we  have  the  same  four 
parties  to  the  bill  as  on  the  Continent.5  (i)  There  is  C.  D.  who 
has  paid  over  money  to  G.  M.  ;  (ii)  there  is  the  drawer  G.  M. ; 
(iii)  there  is  the  drawee  W.  C.  ;  and  (iv)  there  is  the  payee  A  B. 
It  is  also  clear  that  the  bill  has  not  yet  become  a  negotiable 
instrument.  In  the  specimen  Malynes  gives  we  do  not  find  the 
expressions  "order"  or  "bearer."  As  we  have  seen,  it  was  not 
till  after  Malynes  wrote  that  the  development  of  the  negotiable 
character  of  the  bill  of  exchange  took  place  in  continental  states.6 
But  the  need  for  an  instrument  which  admitted  of  some  form  of 
transfer  was  obvious;  and  the  merchants  met  it  by  a  device  not 
unlike  that  which  they  employed  in  the  case  of  bills  obligatory. 
"  Peter  delivereth  five  hundred  pounds  to  John,  who  is  to  give  the 
bill  of  exchange  for  it ;  Peter  taketh  up  five  hundred  pounds  of 
William,  and  may  give  him  the  said  bill  of  John  for  it ;  William 
taketh  up  five  hundred  pounds  of  Nicolas,  and  may  deliver  John 
and  Peter's  bill  for  it ;  Nicolas  taketh  up  five  hundred  pounds  of 
Francis,  and  doth  give  him  the  bill  of  John,  making  mention  of 
Peter  and  William.      Here  are  four  takers-up  of  money,  and  but 

1  The  term  usance  means  the  time  at  which  the  bill  was  payable,  if  not  payable 
at  sight  This  time  varied  according  to  the  custom  of  different  places.  Double  or 
treble  usance  means  double  or  treble  the  customary  time,  and  half  usance  half  the 
customary  time,  Malynes,  op.  cit.  268,  269  ;  Marius,  Practical  Advice,  18. 

2  I.e.  The  Italian  Pagate.  3  Op.  cit.  270  ;  cp.  Marius,  op.  cit.  1. 

4 "If  he  which  doth  underwrite  the  bill  [i.e.  the  acceptor]  is  to  make  himself 
Debitour,  then  he  [the  drawer]  writeth  in  the  bill,  And  put  it  to  my  Account ;  but  if 
he  which  ought  to  pay  it,  and  to  whom  it  is  directed,  is  Debitour  unto  the  drawer, 
then  he  writes,  And  put  it  to  your  Account :  Also  sometimes  it  is  expressed  in  the  bill 
thus,  And  put  it  to  the  Account  of  such  an  one,"  ibid  7. 

8  Above  137.  6  Above  140-145. 


154  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

effectually  one  deliverer  of  money,  which  is  Francis :  for  albeit 
that  Peter  was  the  first  deliverer  of  the  five  hundred  pounds,  he 
became  a  taker  again  of  the  said  money,  receiving  the  same  of 
William  ;  so  that  gradatim  John  is  the  first  taker-up  of  the  said 
five  hundred  pounds,  Peter  is  the  second  taker-up,  William  is  the 
third  taker-up,  and  Nicolas  is  the  fourth  taker-up  of  the  said  five 
hundred  pounds  of  Francis.  To  this  Francis  is  the  bill  of  ex- 
change given,  payable  to  his  friend,  factor  or  servant  in  the  place 
for  which  the  money  was  taken  up.  But  the  said  bill  is  made  by 
John,  the  first  taker-up  of  the  said  money,  declaring,  that  the  value 
of  it  was  received  of  Peter,  for  William  and  for  Nicolas,  upon  the 
account  of  Francis,  which  is  the  last  deliverer  of  the  money  ;  which 
bill  being  paid,  all  the  parties  in  this  exchange  are  satisfied  and 
paid  :  which  is  done  with  great  facility."  l 

This  method  of  assigning  a  bill  of  exchange  had  one  very 
great  advantage  over  that  used  in  the  case  of  bills  obligatory.  All 
the  parties'  names  appeared  on  the  bill,  and  they  could  therefore 
all  be  made  liable  on  it.  "As  for  example,  Francis,  the  party 
who  took  this  bill,  as  being  deliverer  of  it  (the  money)  at  last, 
must  go  a  retrograde  course  herein,  if  John  who  made  the  bill, 
and  was  the  first  taker-up,  do  not  pay  the  same :  Francis  then 
seeketh  Nicolas,  Nicolas  seeketh  William,  William  seeketh  Peter, 
and  Peter  seeketh  John,  the  first  taker-up  of  the  money  of  him. 
Suppose  that  John  is  broken,  then  he  goeth  to  Peter ;  if  Peter  is 
broken,  then  to  William;  if  William  is  broken,  then  to  Nicolas; 
if  Nicolas  is  broken,  then  all  is  lost.  So  that  all  of  them  are 
answerable  to  this  bill  as  above  said."2 

But  this  was  a  cumbersome  process.  The  merchants,  in  their 
efforts  to  find  more  convenient  methods,  were  accustomed  either  to 
send  letters  of  credit,3  or  bills  with  the  names  left  blank  to  be  filled 
up  by  their  foreign  agent,4  or  to  make  the  bill  payable  to  the 
payee  "  or  the  bringer  thereof."  As  to  the  effect  of  these  words, 
when  Malynes  wrote,  I  must  say  a  few  words. 

Malynes  expressly  cautions   merchants    not   to   insert   these 


1  Malynes,  op.  cit.  271.  2  Ibid  274. 

3  "  A  merchant  doth  send  his  friend  or  servant  ...  to  buy  some  commodities  or 
take  up  money  for  some  purpose,  and  doth  deliver  unto  him  an  open  letter,  directed 
to  another  merchant,  requiring  him  that  if  his  friend  .  .  .  the  bearer  of  that  letter 
have  occasion  to  buy  commodities  or  take  up  moneys  .  .  .  that  he  will  .  .  .  procure 
him  the  same  .  .  .  and  he  will  provide  him  the  money,  or  pay  him  by  exchange," 
ibid  76. 

4  "  There  is  also  a  custom  that  a  master  to  his  servant  or  one  friend  to  another 
will  send  bills  of  exchange  with  the  names  in  blank  from  one  country  unto  another, 
as  from  Hamburgh  to  Embden,  or  from  Antwerp  to  Amsterdam,  and  from  thence 
to  Dansic  ;  and  at  Amsterdam  the  names  are  put  in  to  whom  to  be  paid,  and  of  whom 
received,"  ibid  272  ;  a  similar  plan  was  pursued  in  the  case  of  the  bill  obligatory, 
ibid  77. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT         155 

words.1  But  that  they  were  generally  inserted  is  clear  from  some 
of  the  specimens  of  bills  in  the  Admiralty  records,2  and  from  the 
early  seventeenth-century  precedents  of  pleading.3  We  have  seen 
that  abroad  their  insertion  did  not  at  this  period  give  the  bearer 
a  right  to  sue ; 4  and  we  shall  see  that,  when  bills  of  exchange 
became  common  in  the  English  courts,  the  same  rule  was  adopted. 
But  it  would  appear  that,  if  the  bill  contained  these  words,  a  pay- 
ment by  the  acceptor  to  the  bearer  discharged  the  acceptor.5 

Malynes'  book  was  published  in  1622.°  In  165 1  Marius,  a 
notary  public,  published  a  small  tract  giving  practical  advice  upon 
bills  of  exchange."  An  enlarged  edition,  published  in  1670,  was 
said  by  the  author  to  embody  twenty-four  years'  experience  in  his 
profession.  But  it  would  appear  from  the  preface  that  the  new 
edition  did  not  embody  any  very  striking  changes  in  the  law,  but 
rather  consisted  of  a  number  of  additions  to  the  information  given. s 
If  this  be  so,  it  is  clear  that  between  1622  and  1651  very  great 
advances  had  been  made  towards  making  the  bill  of  exchange  a 
negotiable  instrument  And,  having  regard  to  the  state  of  the  law 
on  the  Continent,  this  is  not  surprising.  It  was  during  this  period 
that  the  practice  of  making  bills  payable  to  order,  and  of  trans- 
ferring them  by  indorsement,  was  becoming  common ;  and  it  is 
clear  from  the  French  legislation  that  it  was  becoming  more  and 
more  common  to  make  both  bills  and  other  instruments  payable  to 
bearer.9  All  the  specimens  of  bills  which  Marius  gives  are  made 
payable  to  A  or  assigns  or  to  A  or  order,  and  the  assignment  or 


1 "  Neither  may  you  make  a  bill  of  exchange  payable  to  the  bearer  or  the  bringer 
thereof  (as  you  make  your  bills  obligatory  beyond  the  seas),"  Malynes,  op.  cit,  270. 

■  The  bills  of  1562  and  1563,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  73,  above 
152,  have  this  clause. 

3  Brownlow,  Declarations  (ed.  1659)  266,  267 — the  date  in  the  pleading  is  1605  ; 
Vidian,  Exact  Pleader  (ed.  16S4)  66,  67 — the  date  in  the  pleading  is  1620 ;  in  1622 
West,  Symboleography  §  660,  gives  a  bill  payable  to  R.P.  or  the  bringer  thereof; 
on  the  other  hand  the  pleadings  in  Rastell  f.  10a,  and  the  pleading  in  Heme's 
Pleader  136-137,  which  are  all  from  the  last  half  of  the  sixteenth  century,  do  not  con- 
tain this  clause;  similarly  the  clause  to  A  or  assigns,  though  not  mentioned  by 
Malynes,  was  used  at  this  time;  below  156  n.  1. 

*  Above  124-125. 

5  This  was  clearly  so  when  Marius  wrote,  and  probably  so  when  Malynes  wrote, 
though  he  nowhere  expressly  states  this;  Marius,  Practical  Advice  13,  says,  "  A  bill 
which  shall  be  payable  to  Robert  W.  or  the  bearer  hereof  may  chance  to  miscarry  or 
come  to  a  wrong  man's  hands,  and  he  may  go  and  receive  the  money  upon  such  a  bill 
.  .  .  And  he  that  paid  it  will  produce  the  bill  itself  for  his  warrant  to  pay  it  to  whom- 
soever shall  bring  it"  ;  cp.  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1691)  1  Salk.  125,  where  a  similar 
rule  is  laid  down. 

6  For  Malynes  and  his  book  see  vol.  v  131-134. 

7  My  citations  are  from  the  ed.  of  1684  which  is  contained  in  the  folio  ed.  of 
Malynes'  Lex  Mercatoria. 

8  "  I  have  now  .  .  .  not  only  comprised  what  was  formerly  handled,  and  some- 
thing enlarged  upon  the  same  for  the  better  understanding  thereof  ...  I  have  in  a 
manner  gone  through  the  whole  body  of  Exchange." 

9  Above  125-126,  142. 


156  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

order  is  indorsed  on  the  back.1  Moreover,  it  is  clear  that  the 
assignee  or  indorsee  might  himself  assign  or  indorse  over.2  If  the 
bill  was  indorsed  in  blank  the  holder  might  either  insert  his  own 
name  as  indorsee,  or,  on  getting  payment,  write  a  receipt  for  the 
money.3  That  bills  were  sometimes  also  made  payable  to  bearer 
is  clear  from  Marius's  warning  of  the  dangers  of  the  practice.4  On 
the  other  hand,  a  bill  might  be  payable  to  A  simply.  In  that  case 
it  admitted  of  no  assignment.5 

On  many  other  points  Marius  follows  closely  the  rules  of  law 
observed  on  the  Continent.  Thus  the  rules  as  to  acceptance  for 
honour  ; 6  the  irrevocability  of  acceptance ; 7  protest  in  case  of  non- 
acceptance,  undue  acceptance,  or  non-payment ;  8  days  of  grace  ; 9 
the  efficacy  of  a  verbal  acceptance ; 10  liability  on  a  lost  bill ;  n  the 
liability  of  an  indorser  to  his  own  and,  perhaps,  to  subsequent 
indorsees  12 — all  follow  closely  continental  rules  of  law.  On  the 
question  whether  a  bill  should  be  presented  for  acceptance  as  soon 
as  received,  or  whether  the  holder  should  wait  till  it  falls  due,  he 
strongly  advocates  the  English  custom  that  it  should  be  presented 
as  soon  as  possible,  in  order  that  the  other  parties  to  the  bill  might 
not  be  prejudiced.13    No  doubt  on  this  M  and  upon  other  points  (e.g. 

1  It  may,  however,  be  noted  that,  though  the  clause  to  order  or  to  assigns  does  not 
appear  in  the  specimens  of  bills  which  Malynes  gives,  we  get  the  clause  to  assigns  in  a 
bill  of  1554,  Select  pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (8.S.)  ii  71,  and  also  in  a  pleading  dated 
1627,  Vidian,  Exact  Pleader,  68. 

2  Marius,  op.  cit.  9 — for  the  forms  of  indorsement ;  at  p.  11  he  tells  us  that  on 
outland  bills  (for  these  see  below  158)  three  or  four  assignments  are  often  written. 

3  Marius,  op.  cit.  30 ;  cp.  Lambert  v.  Pack  (1700)  1  Salk.  at  p.  128,  for  a  similar 
ruling  by  Holt,  C.J.,  at  nisi  prius  ;  the  real  name  of  the  case  is  Lambert  v.  Oakes,  see 
note  to  1  Salk.  126  pi.  6,  which  case  is  reported  1  Ld.  Raym.  443. 

4  Above  155  n.  5. 

6  "  If  the  bill  be  made  payable  positively  to  such  a  man,  and  not  to  such  a  man 
or  his  assigns  or  order,  then  an  assignment  on  the  bill  will  not  serve  the  turn,  but 
the  money  in  the  strictness  of  the  letter  must  be  immediately  paid  to  such  a  man  in 
person,  and  he  must  be  known  to  be  the  same  man  mentioned  in  the  bill  of  exchange. 
.  .  .  And  if  the  bill  is  made  payable  positively  to  such  a  man  as  hath  been  said,  such 
a  man's  name  written  on  the  backside  of  the  bill  in  blank,  is  no  sufficient  warrant 
for  another  man  to  come  (as  in  his  name)  to  receive  the  money,  but  the  man  himself  to 
whom  the  bill  is  payable  must  appear  in  person,"  Marius,  op.  cit.  34 ;  this  was  the 
common-law  rule,  see  Hill  v.  Lewis,  1  Salk.  at  p.  133,  per  Holt,  C.J. ;  but  after  the 
statute  of  Anne  (3,  4  Anne  c.  9)  a  note  payable  to  A  simply  was  decided  to  be  a 
promissory  note  within  the  statute,  see  Burchell  v.  Slocock  (1728)  2  Ld.  Raym.  1545  ; 
quare  did  this  make  such  notes  negotiable  ?  It  would  seem  that  it  did,  below 
*73  n.  5  ;  in  England  the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act,  45,  46  Victoria  c.  61  §§  3.1,  8.4, 
89.1,  has  made  the  rule  as  to  notes  applicable  to  bills;  in  the  U.S.A.  the  opposite 
course  has  been  pursued,  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  387. 

6  Marius,  op.  cit.  21,  31.  7  Ibid  20. 

8  Ibid  13,  17,  21,  24,  28,  29.  ,J  Ibid  15,  23,  24.  lu  Ibid  16. 

11  Ibid  19,  20  ;  cp.  below  157  n.  3. 

12  >i  where  there  are  any  assignments  on  bills  negotiated,  always  the  party  tint 
receives  the  value  is  directly  bound  to  him  of  whom  he  hath  received  it,  and  the 
acceptor  to  the  last  assigned,"  ibid  27. 

13  Ibid  12. 

14  Whitehead  v.  Walker  (1842)  9  M.  and  W.  506  at  p.  515  per  Parke,  B. ;  for  the 
present  law  see  45,  46  Victoria  c.  61  §  39, 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT         157 

as  to  the  possibility  of  a  verbal  acceptance,1  as  to  the  validity  of  a 
gratuitous  promise  to  accept,2  and  as  to  the  rights  of  the  parties  on 
a  lost  bill)  3  English  law  was  ultimately  settled  to  be  the  contrary 
of  the  rules  which  he  laid  dowa  But  when  he  wrote,  English  law 
on  this  topic  was,  as  we  shall  see,  but  scanty.  Probably  he  had 
an  accurate  knowledge  of  such  points  of  law  as  had  been  actually 
decided.4  At  any  rate,  it  is  certain  that  the  large  majority  of  his 
rules  upon  points  of  form,  practice,  and  procedure,  have  been 
adopted,  and  are  at  the  present  day  part  of  English  law.5 

It  is  clear  therefore  that,  when  Marius  wrote,  a  bill  of  exchange 
made  payable  to  order  had,  in  mercantile  practice,  acquired  one  of 
the  most  important  elements  of  negotiability — a  capacity  to  be 
transferred  indefinitely  by  indorsement  and  delivery.  On  the 
other  hand,  a  bill  of  exchange  made  payable  to  bearer  was  probably 
still  in  the  same  position  as  it  was  in  when  Malynes  wrote.  But 
Marius  leaves  us  uncertain  as  to  how  far  these  bills  possessed  the 
other  two  elements  of  negotiability — the  capacity  of  a  bona  fide 
holder  for  value  to  get  a  better  title  than  his  transferor,  and  the 
presumption  of  consideration.  Thus  he  says  nothing  at  all  on  the 
question  whether  a  holder  of  a  bill  in  good  faith,  who  has  acquired 
it  from  one  who  had  no  title  or  a  defective  title,  can  sue  upon  it. 
But  it  would  appear  from  Malynes  that  mercantile  opinion  was  in 
favour  of  the  view  that  an  acceptor  was  always  prima  facie  liable 
to  pay  ;  and  that  the  facts  (i)  that  the  drawer  had  become  insolvent 
since  the  acceptance ;  and  (ii)  that  the  drawer  had  not  received 
value  from  the  payee— were  no  valid  defences  to  an  action  by  the 
holder.6  On  the  other  hand,  Marius  would  seem  to  be  of  opinion 
that  if  the  payee  had  not  given  value,  and  the  drawer  had  satisfied 

1  Marius  16  ;  for  the  subsequent  development  of  the  law  see  Hindhaugh  v.  Blakey 
(1878)  3  C.P.D.  at  pp.  139-141 ;  that  case  decided  that  the  bare  signature  was  not 
enough  ;  but  this  was  overruled  by  41,  42  Victoria  c.  13  ;  repealed  and  re-enacted  by 
the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act,  45,  46  Victoria  c.  61  §  17  (2)  (a). 

2  Marius  16 ;  Johnson  v.  Collings  (1800)  1  East  98  ;  Street,  op.  cit.  399-401. 

3  Marius  19,  20 ;  Hansard   v.  Robinson  (1827)  7  B.  and  C.  90 ;  Street,  op.  cit. 

375-376- 

4  Thus,  as  Street  points  out,  op.  cit.  ii  376,  he  knows  that  the  proper  form  of 
action  against  the  acceptor  is  not  assumpsit,  but  an  action  on  the  case  based  upon  the 
custom. 

5  See  e.g.  Tassell  v.  Lee,  1  Ld.  Raym.  743 — approval  by  Holt,  C.J.,  of  the 
mercantile  customs  of  protest  and  days  of  grace. 

6 Lex  Mercatoria  274 — the  case  was  as  follows: — A  merchant  at  Antwerp  drew 
on  a  merchant  in  London  for  £800  to  pay  a  creditor  of  his  in  Antwerp.  The  London 
merchant  accepted  these  bills ;  and  then  the  drawer  became  insolvent.  The  acceptor 
then  stated  that  he  would  not  pay  the  bills  because  the  insolvent  drawer  had  not 
received  value  of  the  payee — though  in  fact  the  bills  had  acknowledged  the  receipt 
of  value.  The  answer  given  to  this  was  that  the  acceptor  must  pay  because  "  for 
other  matters  they  had  nothing  to  do  therewith."  The  acceptor  then  died  and  no 
decision  was  reached  ;  but,  says  Malynes,  "the  opinion  of  other  merchants  and  my 
own  is,  that  the  acceptor  of  the  bill  was  to  pay  them,  and  his  heirs  and  executors  are 
liable  thereto,  unless  there  were  found  an  apparent  combination  and  practice  in  it 
between  the  two  merchants  of  Antwerp,  as  was  by  many  suspected." 


158  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  person  who  had  given  value,  neither  the  payee  nor  subsequent 
indorsees  could  sue  the  drawer  ;  for  the  payee's  right  to  sue  was 
based,  as  it  was  abroad,  on  the  fact  that  he  was  either  the  deliverer 
of  the  money  to  the  drawer,  or  the  principal  or  agent  of  such 
deliverer,  or  a  creditor  of  the  drawer  by  reason  of  some  precedent 
debt.1  But  it  would  appear  that  the  acceptor  remained  liable  to 
the  drawer,  and  perhaps  to  subsequent  indorsees.2  It  is  clear  that 
much  was  still  uncertain.  Of  the  three  main  features  of  negotia- 
bility the  bill  of  exchange  was  only  just  beginning  to  acquire  one 
— the  feature  of  ready  transferability.  But  though  its  negotiable 
character  was  as  yet  in  germ,  it  had  began  to  develop  in  two  other 
directions. 

In  the  first  place,  it  had  ceased  to  be  used  only  in  connection 
with  foreign  trade.  It  could  be  used  equally  well  in  connection 
with  internal  trade.  If  used  in  connection  with  foreign  trade,  it 
was  called  an  outland  bill ;  if  used  in  connection  with  internal 
trade  it  was  called  an  inland  bill.3  In  the  second  place,  though 
four  parties  were  still  normally  requisite  to  the  making  of  a  bill,4 
a  bill  could  be  made  as  between  three  and  sometimes  as  between 
only  two  parties.5 

1  Marius,  op.  cit.  35 — "  If  a  bill  of  exchange  be  made  payable  to  one  man,  for  the 
value  received  of  another  man,  and  the  party  on  whom  the  bill  is  drawn  hath 
accepted  the  bill,  but  .  .  .  faileth  in  the  payment,  and  hereupon  protest  is  made,  and 
by  vertue  of  that  protest  the  party  which  delivered  the  value  doth  recover  satisfaction 
of  the  drawer ;  I  say,  in  this  case  the  drawer  is  freely  discharged  against  the  party  or 
parties  to  whom  the  said  bill  was  made  payable,  either  immediately  in  the  bill,  or 
mediately  by  assignment  or  assignments  were  they  never  so  many  on  the  bill." 

2  "  Neither  can  he  to  whom  the  bill  is  first  made  payable  (if  but  an  assign  of  the 
deliverer)  prosecute  the  acceptor  (after  the  drawer  hath  given  satisfaction  to  the 
party  which  delivered  the  value)  "...  but,  "  the  acceptor  is  not  totally  discharged. 
...  In  reference  to  the  party  that  delivered  the  value  first,  and  the  party  to  whom 
the  bill  was  payable  (supposing  himself  to  be  but  an  assign  of  the  deliverer)  the 
acceptor  doth  but  confirm  what  the  drawer  hath  done,  and  the  drawer  having  made 
satisfaction  to  the  deliverer,  the  acceptor  is  likewise  discharged  against  the  deliverer, 
and  against  the  party  to  whom  the  bill  was  first  payable  (if  he  be  but  an  assign) ;  but 
the  acceptor,  by  vertue  of  his  acceptance,  makes  himself  debitor,  and  is  still  liable  to 
the  drawer,  or  to  the  account  for  which  he  accepted  the  bill,  until  satisfaction  be 
given,"  ibid. 

3  Ibid  2 — but  Marius  thinks  it  necessary  to  state  that  these  inland  bills  are 
"as  effectual  and  binding"  as  outland  bills;  he  cites  a  book  of  John  Trenchant 
on  arithmetic,  printed  at  Lyons  in  1608,  for  the  older  view  that  properly  Exchange 
should  only  be  recognized  as  between  towns  "in  subjection  unto  divers  lords,"  who 
do  not  allow  the  transport  of  money,  or  because  of  the  risk  of  loss  in  transport ;  in 
some  of  the  earlier  pleadings  only  outland  bills  seem  to  be  contemplated  as  valid  by 
the  custom,  see  e.g.  Liber  Placitandi  (1674)  41 — a  precedent  dated  1636 ;  the  bill  of 
exchange  mentioned  in  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  578  is  an  outland  bill. 

4  Marius,  op.  cit.  2 ;  above  153. 

5  "  First  the  drawer,  and  secondly  the  party  on  whom  it  is  drawn ;  the  drawer  he 
makes  a  bill  of  exchange  payable  to  himself  or  order  for  the  value  in  himself,  and 
subscribes  the  bill,  and  directs  it  to  the  party  that  oweth  him  money,  and  is  to  pay  it 
by  exchange,  by  which  bill  (when  the  party  on  whom  it  is  drawn  hath  accepted  it)  he 
becometh  debtour  to  the  drawer,  and  he  before  the  bill  falls  due,  doth  negotiate  the 
parcel  with  another  man,  and  so  draws  in  the  money  at  the  place  where  he  liveth," 
ibid ;  cp.  Buller  v.  Crips  (1702)  6  Mod.  at  p.  30  per  Holt,  C.J. 


THE  ENGLISH   DEVELOPMENT         159 

These  two  developments  show  us  that  in  England,  as  abroad, 
the  process  is  begun  which  will  make  the  bill  of  exchange  a  form 
of  paper  currency.1  But  as  yet  it  is  only  begun ;  and  we  shall  see 
that  some  of  these  developments  tended  to  make  English  lawyers, 
whose  acquaintance  with  these  mercantile  instruments  was  as  yet 
slight,  confuse  the  bill  of  exchange  with  those  bills  obligatory  or 
bills  of  debt,  to  which  the  merchants  were  endeavouring  to  give 
somewhat  the  same  transferability  as  the  bill  of  exchange  had 
acquired.  Of  this,  however,  I  cannot  speak  till  I  have  examined 
the  process  by  which  the  bill  of  exchange  was  received  into  Eng- 
lish law,  and  its  negotiable  characteristics  developed  by  the  courts 
of  common  law. 

(ii)  The  recognition  and  development  of  the  bill  of  exchange  in 
English  law. 

It  was  the  development  of  the  action  of  assumpsit  which  gave 
to  English  lawyers  a  form  of  action  well  fitted  to  enforce  many 
various  kinds  of  mercantile  contracts.2  In  the  latter  part  of  the 
sixteenth  century  it  occurred  to  some  lawyers  that  it  might  be  used 
to  enforce  the  rights  of  the  parties  to  a  bill  of  exchange.  The  first 
edition  of  Rastell's  Entries,  which  was  published  in  1564,  contains 
a  pleading  in  which  this  attempt  was  made;3  and  the  second 
edition,  published  in  1670,  contains  two  more  precedents  of  the 
years  1595  and  1596.4  In  Heme's  book  on  pleading  there  is 
another  precedent,  taken  from  a  court  roll  of  the  year  1586,  in 
which  a  similar  attempt  was  crowned  with  success ; 3  and  in 
Martin  v.  Boure6  (1602) — the  earliest  reported  case  on  a  bill  of 
exchange — assumpsit  was  again  adapted  to  enforce  the  rights  of 
some  of  the  parties,  and  again  with  success. 

But  these  authorities  show  us  that  the  statement,  in  the  terms 
of  assumpsit,  of  the  rights  of  the  parties  to  a  bill  of  exchange,  was 
as  difficult  for  the  common  lawyers  as  the  statement  of  these  rights, 
in  the  terms  of  the  Roman  law  of  obligatio,  was  for  the  civilians.7 
The  precedent  in  Rastell's  first  edition  sets  out  that  one  A  had 
delivered  money  to  B  (the  drawer) ;  that  in  return  for  this  money 
B  had  promised  that  one  John  of  G.  (the  drawee)  would  pay  a 
certain  sum  to  Reginald  S.  (the  payee),  who  was  the  factor  of  A ; 
and  if  John  of  G.  did  not  pay,  that  then  B  would  do  so ;  it  then 
avers  that  the  drawee  had  not  paid  the  money  to  the  payee, 

1  Above  145.  2  Vol.  iii  428  seqq. 

3At  f.  io»,  cited  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  341  n.  1,  and  Cranch, 
Promissory  Notes,  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  76-77 ;  for  this  book  see  vol.  v  384,  vol.  vi  6S3. 

4  Rastell,  Entries  ff.  338a-33ga. 

B  Heme's  Pleader  (ed.  1657)  136-137,  the  reference  given  is  Trin.  13  Eliza.  Rot. 
mmxxi ;  for  this  book  see  vol.  v  385. 

«Cro.  Jac.  6.  7  Above  137-140. 


160  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and  that,  if  he  had  done  so,  the  money  would  have  come  to  the 
profit  of  A  ;  and  that  B  (the  drawer)  has  refused  to  fulfil  his  contract 
by  paying  it.  It  is  fairly  clear  that  this  is  an  action  against  a 
drawer  by  a  deliverer  of  the  money,  who  was  in  substance  the 
principal  of  the  payee.1  As  we  have  seen,  the  payee's  right  of 
action  was  explained  in  a  similar  way  by  continental  jurists.2  The 
pleadings  in  Rastell's  later  edition,  and  in  Heme,  are  adapted  to 
actions  by  a  payee  against  an  acceptor  and  a  drawer  respectively. 
All  these  later  precedents  are  more  explicit  than  Rastell's  earliest 
precedent,  in  that  the  instrument  is  termed  a  "  bill  of  exchange,"  and 
reference  is  made  to  the  custom  of  the  merchants.  But  they  all 
state  the  cause  of  action  in  a  somewhat  similar  manner.  Thus  the 
precedent  in  Heme's  book  alleges  that  W  (the  deliverer  of  the 
money  and  the  payee)  paid  money  in  England  to  H  (the  drawer)  ; 
that  H  in  consideration  thereof  promised  to  pay  to  W  at  Hamburg 
a  certain  sum  in  two  months  time ;  that  in  fulfilment  of  this  con- 
tract H  gave  to  W  "  his  bill  of  exchange  made  according  to  the 
use  of  merchants,"  whereby  he  directed  his  factor  R  (the  drawee) 
to  pay  the  money ;  that  R  promised  to  pay  the  money  (i.e.  he  ac- 
cepted the  bill)  ;  and  that  in  breach  of  his  promise  he  had  neglected 
to  do  so.  The  facts  in  the  case  of  Martin  v.  Boure  are  rather  more 
complicated,  and  the  pleadings  as  summarized  in  the  report  are 
somewhat  obscure.  But  it  would  seem  that  the  action  was  brought 
by  the  drawer  against  the  acceptor  for  a  failure  on  the  part  of  the 
acceptor  to  pay,  in  consequence  of  which  failure  he  (the  drawer) 
had  been  obliged  to  pay  to  the  payee.3 

It  was  shortly  after  the  decision  in  this  case  that  the  pleaders 
adopted  another  and  a  much  more  satisfactory  device  for  stating 
the  rights  of  the  parties.  We  have  seen  that,  at  the  beginning  of 
the  seventeenth  century,  it  was  coming  to  be  generally  admitted 
that  a  general  mercantile  custom  was  a  part  of  the  common  law.4 
It  followed  that  in  these  actions  it  would  be  sufficient  to  state  the 
facts,  and  allege  that  the  rights  and  duties  of  the  various  parties  to 
the  bill  arose  merely  by  virtue  of  this  custom.  This  course  was 
followed  in  Oaste  v.  Taylor'*  in  1612,  and  in  all  subsequent  cases. 
In  many  of  them  the  custom  relied  upon  is  stated  at  considerable 
length.6  At  the  end  of  the  century  a  step  further  was  taken  in 
the  direction  of  simplifying  the  pleadings.     It  was  said  that  these 

1  Above  137.  -  Above  139-140. 

3  See  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  347.  4  Vol.  v  145. 

5  Cro.  Jac.  306 ;  as  Street  says,  op.  cit.  ii  348-349,  "  upon  reference  to  pleadings 
in  that  case  the  reader  will  see  what  lengthy  recitals  could  be  pared  off  upon  accept- 
ance of  the  idea  of  duty  arising  from  a  custom  of  merchants." 

6  See  the  recitals  in  Brownlow,  Declarations  (ed.  1659)  266-267 ;  Vidian,  the  Exact 
Pleader  66,  67,  70 ;  Cramlington  v.  Evans  (1691)  2  Vent.  298,  300 ;  cp.  Barnaby  v. 
Rigalt  (1633)  Cro.  Car.  301-302. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        161 

mercantile  customs  being  part  of  the  common  law  it  was  unneces- 
sary to  plead  them  specially.1 

These  changes  in  methods  of  pleading  effected,  as  Mr.  Street 
has  said,2  a  great  simplification  in  the  statement  of  cases  turning 
on  these  bills.  They  also  had,  as  changes  of  pleading  very  often 
have,  a  considerable  effect  upon  the  development  of  the  law.  Under 
cover  of  these  convenient  phrases  about  the  custom  of  the  mer- 
chants, it  was  easy  to  introduce  into  the  common  law  both  the 
legal  principles  familiar  to  continental  lawyers,  and  the  commercial 
practices  familiar  both  to  English  and  to  foreign  merchants.  The 
common  law  entered  into  the  fruit  of  the  labours  of  many  genera- 
tions of  continental  lawyers  and  merchants,  when  it  thus  took  over 
the  bill  of  exchange  at  the  stage  of  development  which  it  had 
reached  in  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century. 

The  manner  in  which  the  judges  incorporated  the  law  as  to  bills 
of  exchange  with  the  common  law  can  be  read  in  the  reports  of  the 
seventeenth  century — more  especially  in  the  reports  of  the  last  years 
of  that  century,  during  Holt's  tenure  of  the  office  of  chief  justice 
of  the  King's  Bench.  From  these  reports  we  can  gather  that  the 
common  law  was  beginning  to  possess  a  body  of  doctrine  upon  the 
rights  of  the  parties  to  bills  of  exchange;  that  the  negotiable 
character  of  these  bills  was  beginning  to  emerge  with  some  clear- 
ness ;  and  that  the  administration  of  the  law  relating  to  them  by 
the  common  law  courts,  was  beginning  to  differentiate  the  English 
law  as  to  bills  of  exchange  from  that  of  the  Continent. 

(f)  The  rights  of  the  parties. 

Let  us  recall  the  rights  of  the  four  normal  parties  to  the  bill  of 
exchange,  and  see  how  they  were  envisaged  by  the  common  law.3 
(a)  The  relations  of  the  person  who  has  paid  over  the  money,  which 
he  wishes  to  remit,  to  the  drawer  who  has  received  it.  It  would 
seem  from  the  books  of  precedents  of  the  latter  part  of  the  six- 
teenth and  of  the  seventeenth  century,  that  his  rights  in  England 
were  based  upon  substantially  the  same  ground  as  that  upon 
which  they  were  based  abroad.  The  drawer,  who  has  received 
money  from  the  remitter,  must  fulfil  his  contract  by  paying  it  over  to 
the  person  on  whose  behalf  he  has  received  it4     (J?)  The  relations 

1  Williams  v.  Williams  (1694)  Carth.  269,  270 :  "  'tis  needless  to  set  forth  the 
custom  specially  in  the  declaration,  for  'tis  sufficient  to  say  that  such  a  person  secun- 
dum usum  et  consuetudinem  mercatorum  drew  the  bill ;  therefore  all  the  matter  in 
the  declaration  concerning  the  special  custom  was  merely  surplusage,  and  the  declara- 
tion good  without  it "  ;  Bromwich  v.  Lloyd  (1698)  2  Lut.  1585  ;  cp.  vol.  v  145-146. 

3  Op.  cit,  ii  348,  349. 

3  See  above  137-140  for  the  continental  law. 

*  Rastell,  Entries  338b ;  Vidian,  op.  cit,  66-67 ;  Woodward  v.  Rowe  (1666)  2  Keb. 
106 — "  By  the  common  law  a  man  may  resort  to  him  that  received  the  money  if  he  to 
whom  the  bill  was  directed  refuse  " ;  Mogadara  v.  Holt  (1692)  Holt  114 — "  The  drawer 
is  chargeable  by  the  value  received,"  per  Holt,  C.J. 
VOL.  VIII.— II 


162  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

of  drawer  and  drawee.  The  books  would  seem  to  show  that 
their  relations  were  based,  either  upon  the  fact  that  the  drawee  was 
the  agent  of  the  drawer,1  or  that  he  is  the  debtor  of  the  drawer.2 
(c)  The  relations  of  acceptor  and  payee.  The  cases  make  it  quite 
clear  that  the  courts  adopted  the  principle  that  an  acceptance  was 
equivalent  to  a  promise  to  pay,  upon  which,  by  the  custom  of  the 
merchants,  an  action  lay.3  But  it  was  clear,  in  some  cases  at  least, 
that  the  consideration  for  this  promise  did  not  move  from  the  payee. 
Thus  if  A  gives  money  to  B  to  transmit  to  C,  and  B  draws  a  bill 
on  X  in  favour  of  C  which  X  accepts,  there  is  no  consideration 
moving  from  C  to  X.  It  follows  that  there  is  no  privity  of  contract 
between  them.  It  was  therefore  held  that  the  payee  could  not  sue 
in  debt  or  indebitatus  assumpsit,  but  must  make  use  of  an  action 
on  the  case  based  on  the  custom.4  In  other  words,  the  common 
law  recognized  the  liability,  recognized  that  it  was  not  contractual, 
and  therefore,  without  further  analysis  allowed  an  action  on  the  case 
to  enforce  a  custom  of  which  it  approved,  (d)  The  relations  of  the 
pavee  and  drawer.  Here  again  the  courts  followed  mercantile 
custom  and  continental  law,  by  basing  the  payee's  right  of  recourse 
against  the  drawer,  in  the  event  of  non-acceptance  or  of  non-pay- 
ment by  the  acceptor,  upon  the  existence  of  some  sort  of  agency 
between  the  payee  and  the  person  who  had  given  value  to  the 
drawer.  This  relation  of  agency  was  often  set  out  in  the  earlier 
pleadings.5  In  1666  the  Court  stated  that  it  would  always  be 
presumed.6  But  a  relationship  which  will  always  be  presumed  is 
generally  becoming  fictitious.  By  the  end  of  this  period  the 
drawer's  liability  is  coming  to  be  based  upon  a  different  ground. 
It  is  said  that  the  act  of  drawing  a  bill  implies  a  warranty  to  the 
payee  that  it  will  be  paid.7     The  use  of  a  term,  which  is  reminis- 

1  Rastell,  Entries  338a ;  Heme,  Pleader  136 ;  but  the  cause  of  action  is  sometimes 
stated  more  generally.  Thus  in  a  precedent,  which  is  dated  1636,  it  is  stated  that 
according  to  mercantile  custom  (which  as  usual  is  set  out  at  some  length)  if  one  mer- 
chant (A)  draws  on  another  (B),  and  B  refuses  to  pay,  A  becomes  liable  ;  and  A  on 
this  ground  claims  to  hold  B  liable,  Liber  Placitandi  (1674)  41-42. 

2  See  the  facts  as  found  by  inquisition  in  Cramlington  v.  Evans  (1691)  2  Vent,  at 
p.  309. 

3  (1613)  Oaste  v.  Taylor,  Cro.  Jac.  306 ;  Barnaby  v.  Rigalt  (1635)  Cro.  Car.  301-302. 

4  Brown  v.  London  (1670)  1  Vent.  152;  1  Mod.  285,  and  note  to  the  report  in 
Modern  ;  Rainsford,  C.J.,  said,  "  This  is  the  very  same  with  Milton's  Case  .  .  .  where 
it  was  adjudged  that  an  indebitatus  assumpsit  would  not  lie  .  .  .  we  all  agreed  that 
a  bill  of  exchange  accepted,  &c,  was  indeed  a  good  ground  for  a  special  action  upon 
the  case;  but  that  it  did  not  make  a  debt " ;  cp.  Hodges  v.  steward  (1692)  1  Salk.  125. 

5  Rastell,  Entries  ff.  10a,  339a ;  cp.  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  352 

6  Woodward  v.  Rowe  (1666)  2  Keb.  133 — An  action  against  the  drawer,  and, 
"  Judgment  pro  plaintiff  (the  payee)  per  totam  curiam,  and  they  will  intend  that  he  of 
whom  the  value  is  said  to  be  received  by  the  defendant  was  the  plaintiff's  servant." 

7  Starke  v.  Cheeseman  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  538 — Holt,  C.J.,  said,  "  He  who  draws 
a  bill  warrants  the  payment  of  it,  and  if  he  does  not,  it  is  a  deceit,  and  one  may  have 
an  action  upon  it  "  ;  the  report  goes  on  to  state  that  the  plaintiff  afterwards  got  judg- 
ment because  "the  drawing  of  a  bill  was  an  actual  promise";   cp.  Claxton  v.  Swift 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        163 

cent  of  the  sale  of  goods,  is  perhaps  a  sign  that  it  is  coming  to  be 
recognized  that  the  bill  operates  as  a  conveyance  as  well  as  con- 
ferring contractual  rights.1  But  as  yet  this  idea  is  new,  and  the 
courts  have  not  grasped  it  firmly.  Here,  as  in  other  cases,  the 
courts  were  generally  satisfied  with  stating  that,  by  the  custom  of 
the  merchants,  the  drawer  is  liable  to  the  payee  in  the  event  of 
non-acceptance  or  of  non-payment  by  the  acceptor,  and  with  giv- 
ing effect  to  the  custom.  We  must  wait  till  the  following  period 
for  the  more  extensive  use  of  the  idea  of  warranty  to  explain  the 
liabilities  inter  se  of  the  various  parties  to  a  bill.2 

I  have  not  yet  described  all  the  possible  parties  to  a  bill  of 
exchange.  There  are  also  the  rights  of  indorsers  and  indorsees, 
and  of  the  bearer  of  a  bill  made  payable  to  X  or  bearer.  But 
their  position  I  can  best  deal  with  under  the  next  head. 

(it)  The  negotiable  character  of  the  bill  of  exchange. 

We  have  seen  that  the  quality  of  negotiability  includes  three 
main  peculiarities — (a)  the  mode  of  transfer  ;  (b)  the  fact  that  the 
title  of  the  holder  is  unaffected  by  defects  in  or  the  absence  of  title 
on  the  part  of  his  transferor ;  and  (c)  the  presumption  of  considera- 
tion.3 The  reports  show  us  that,  by  the  end  of  the  century,  all 
these  peculiarities  were  beginning  to  be  recognized. 

(a)  It  was  recognized  that  if  a  bill  was  payable  to  X  or  order, 
or  to  X  or  his  assigns,  the  bill  could  be  transferred  by  indorsement 
and  delivery ; 4  and  further,  that  the  indorsee  could  in  like  manner 
transfer  his  rights.5  On  the  other  hand,  a  bill  which  was  payable 
to  X  simply  could  not  be  so  transferred.6  The  rights  of  the 
indorsees  depended  upon  the  principle  that  each  indorsement 
amounted    in    substance  to  the  drawing  of  a  new   bill.7      The 

(1687)  Comb.  32-33,  the  indorser's  liability  is  explained  by  reference  to  the  law  as  to 
warranty — "  no  case  in  law  resembles  this,  but  that  of  a  warranty  "  ;  cp.  Anon.  (1694) 
Holt  115. 

1  Above  142-143,  145  ;  we  see  the  same  idea  in  an  anonymous  nisi  prius  case  of 
1699  reported  1  Salk.  126 ;  it  was  ruled  that  trover  would  lie  against  the  finder  of 
a  lost  bank  bill,  but  not  against  his  assignee,  "  by  reason  of  the  course  of  trade  which 
creates  a  property  in  the  assignee  or  bearer." 

2  See  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  411-415  ;  cp.  45,  46  Victoria  c.  61  §§  54-56. 

3  Above  113-114. 

*  "  When  the  bill  is  payable  to  J.S.  or  order  there  an  express  power  is  given  to  the 
party  to  assign,  and  the  indorsee  may  maintain  an  action,"  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1692) 
1  Salk.  125. 

8  "  As  to  the  appointment,  this  will  not  make  an  order  at  common  law,  because 
there  are  two  indorsements;  and  if  I  give  my  servant  an  authority  to  receive,  he 
cannot  authorize  another ;  otherwise  if  but  one ;  then  payment  to  the  first  indorsee 
would  be  a  payment  to  the  person,  therefore  you  here  depend  upon  the  law  of 
merchants,  which  at  present  I  think  we  ought  to  take  notice  of,"  per  Ventris,  J.,  Carter 
v.  Downish  (1686)  at  p.  130  ;  cp.  above  141-143  for  the  growth  of  this  principle  on  the 
Continent. 

•Above  156. 

7  Williams  v.  Field  (1694)  3  Salk.  68— "  Every  indorsement  is  a  new  bill  and 
implies  a  warranty  by  the  indorser  that  the  money  shall  be  paid":  Harry  v,  Perrit 
(1711)  1  Salk.  133.  ' 


164  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

indorsee's  right  against  his  indorser  therefore  depended  upon  the 
same  principle  as  the  right  of  the  payee  against  the  drawer.1  The 
indorser  by  indorsing  warrants  that  the  indorsee  shall  be  paid. 
From  this  principle  two  consequences  flowed.  In  the  first  place, 
the  last  indorsee  could  sue  any  of  the  indorsers,  as  well  as  the 
drawer;2  and,  after  some  hesitation,  it  was  held  that  each  indorser 
could  be  made  primarily  liable  on  the  bill,  and  not  merely  liable 
only  in  the  event  of  the  drawer  failing  to  pay.3  In  the  second  place, 
although  a  bill  made  payable  to  A  simply  did  not  admit  of  transfer, 
yet  if  A  indorsed  it  to  B,  and  B  to  C,  C  could  sue  B  or  A  upon 
their  indorsements.4 

It  was  only  if  a  bill  was  payable  to  A  or  order  or  to  A  or  assigns 
that  it  was  transferable.  It  was  held,  after  a  little  hesitation,  that 
a  bill  payable  to  A  or  bearer  was  not  so  transferable.5  It  was 
treated  as  a  bill  payable  to  A  simply.  It  is  true  that  if  the  bill 
were  made  payable  to  bearer,  a  payment  to  the  bearer  would  dis- 
charge the  acceptor ; 6  but  the  bearer  could  not  sue  on  such  a  bill 
in  his  own  name.  He  could  only  sue  in  the  name  of  the  person  to 
whom  the  bill  was  payable.7  It  is  probable  that  the  judges,  when 
they  laid  down  this  rule,  were  influenced  by  the  prevailing  conti- 
nental practice.  We  have  seen  that  it  was  not  till  1721  that  the 
bearer  was  given  a  right  of  action  in  France ; 8  and  it  was  not  till 
1764  that  it  was  clearly  and  finally  laid  down  by  the  English 
courts,  in  the  case  of  Grant  v.  Vaughan?  that  the  bearer  of  a  bill  of 
exchange,  made  payable  to  A  or  bearer,  had  an  independent  right 
of  action.  This  development  was  assisted  by  the  fact  that,  long 
before  that  date,  the  Legislature  had  allowed  the  bearer  of  a 
promissory  note,  made  payable  to  bearer,  to  sue  in  his  own  name.10 
The  older  cases  do  not,  as  we  shall  see,  distinguish  very  clearly 
between  notes  and  bills.11     It  was  thus  possible  to  apply  the  law 

1  Above  162-163.  2  Williams  v.  Field  (1694)  3  Salk.  68. 

3  Holt,  C.J.,  ruled  in  Lambert  v.  Pack  (1700)  1  Salk.  127,  that  a  demand  on  the 
drawer  must  be  proved  before  the  indorser  could  be  sued ;  this  was  dissented  from 
in  Harry  v.  Perrit  (171 1)  1  Salk.  133,  and  overruled  in  Bomley  v.  Frazier  (1722)  1  Str. 
441,  on  the  ground  that  the  delay  so  caused  would  impede  the  circulation  of  these 
bills ;  cp.  Haylyn  v.  Adamson  (1758)  2  Burr,  at  pp.  675,  676. 

4  Hill  v.  Lewis  (1709)  1  Salk  at  p.  133 — "  The  indorsement  of  a  bill  which  has 
not  the  words,  or  to  his  order,  is  good,  or  of  the  same  effect  betwixt  the  indorser  and 
the  indorsee,  to  make  the  indorser  chargeable  to  the  indorsee." 

s  Hinton's  case  (1682)  2  Shower  236,  the  bearer  of  a  bill  of  exchange  made  payable 
to  J.S.  or  bearer  sued,  and  Pemberton,  C.J.,  ruled  "that  he  must  entitle  himself  to 
it  on  a  valuable  consideration  ...  for  if  he  come  to  be  bearer  by  casualty  or  knavery 
he  shall  not  have  the  benefit  of  it " ;  it  was  held  in  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1692)  1 
Salk.  125  that  a  bill  so  drawn  was  not  assignable;  the  reason  given  in  Nicholson  v. 
Sedgwick  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  181  was  that  "  if  the  bearer  be  allowed  to  bring 
the  action  in  his  own  name,  it  may  be  very  inconvenient ;  for  then  anyone,  who  finds 
the  note  by  accident,  may  bring  the  action." 

6  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1692)  1  Salk.  125. 

7  Nicholson  v.  Sedgwick  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  181. 
•Above  125-126.  93  Burr.  1516. 

10  Below  173.  u  Below  171. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        165 

as  to  notes  to  bills  ;  and  give  to  bills  to  bearer  the  same  advant- 
ages that  bills  to  order  had  previously  enjoyed  '  It  followed  that, 
in  the  case  of  a  bill  to  order  indorsed  in  blank,  the  holder  could 
sue  as  the  bearer.1  He  was  no  longer  obliged  (as  he  was  in  this 
period)  either  to  fill  up  the  blank  and  sue  in  his  own  name,  or 
leave  the  blank  not  filled  up  and  sue  in  the  name  of  the  indorser.2 
(£)  It  was  during  this  period  that  the  right  of  the  bona  fide 
holder  for  value  to  recover  on  a  bill,  notwithstanding  a  defect  in  or 
even  an  absence  of  title  on  the  part  of  his  transferor,  was  gradually 
gaining  recognition.  This  feature  of  negotiability — the  most  im- 
portant and  the  most  characteristic  of  all  its  features  —  was  not  yet 
clearly  defined.  It  was  not  yet  clearly  defined  mainly  because  the 
rights  of  the  bearer  as  such  were  not  yet  clearly  recognized.  We 
have  seen  that  it  rests  ultimately  upon  the  view  that  the  acceptor, 
or  other  party  liable  upon  the  bill,  has  contracted  to  pay  any  one 
who  is  the  bearer  in  the  case  of  an  instrument  payable  to  bearer,  or 
any  bearer  in  whose  favour  an  order  has  been  indorsed  on  the  bill 
in  the  case  of  an  instrument  payable  to  order.3  It  is  in  the  case 
of  a  bearer  instrument  that  this  most  clearly  appears,  because  the 
bearer  cannot,  as  Mr.  Street  puts  it,4  be  treated  "as  an  attorney  or 
representative,  or  as  taking  by  mere  assignment  an  estate  that  had 
been  vested  in  another."  He  must  be  treated  "as  taking  his  title 
directly  from  the  grantor  " ;  and  the  grantor  must  be  treated  as 
contracting  directly  with  him.  This  view  is  clearly  expressed  in 
one  of  the  cases  of  the  late  seventeenth  century,  in  which  the  courts 
had  adopted  the  view  (maintained  by  the  court  of  Chancery 5  but 
afterwards  dissented  from  by  the  courts  of  common  law 6)  that  the 
bearer  of  a  note  payable  to  bearer  could  sue: — "Traditio  facit 
chartam  loqui:  and  by  the  delivery  he  expounds  the  person  before 
meant ;  as  when  a  merchant  promises  to  pay  to  "  the  bearer  "  of  the 
note,  any  one  that  brings  the  note  shall  be  paid."  "  It  was  not  till 
the  independent  rights  of  the  bearer  were  recognized  by  the  cases 
decided  in  the  latter  half  of  the  eighteenth  century,  that  the  rights 

1  Peacock  v.  Rhodes  (1781)  2  Dougl.  at  p.  636:  "I  see  no  difference  between  a 
note  indorsed  blank,  and  one  payable  to  bearer,"  per  Lord  Mansfield. 

a  Clark  v.  Pigot  (1699)  *  Salk-  126 — the  plaintiff  having  a  bill  payable  to  himself 
or  order  indorsed  it  in  blank  and  sent  it  to  J.S.  The  money  not  having  been  paid,  he 
sued  the  acceptor.  Holt,  C.J.,  said,  "  J.S.  had  it  in  his  power  to  act  either  as  servant 
or  assignee  :  if  he  had  filled  up  the  blank  space  making  the  bill  payable  to  him,  that 
would  have  witnessed  his  election  to  have  received  it  as  indorsee;  but  that  being 
omitted,  his  intention  is  presumed  to  act  only  as  servant  to  Clark." 

3  Above  144.  *  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  ii  370-371. 

'Crawley  v.  Crowther  (1702)  Freeman,  Cases  in  Chy.  258. 

6  Above  164  a.  5. 

7  Shelden  v.  Hentley  (1681)  2  Show,  at  p.  161 ;  cp.  Crawley  v.  Crowther  (1702) 
Freeman,  Cases  in  Chy.  258  where  it  is  said  that,  "  If  a  bill  be  payable  to  A  or  bearer, 
it  is  like  so  much  money  paid  to  whomsoever  the  note  is  given,  that  let  what  accounts 
or  conditions  soever  be  between  the  party  who  gives  the  note  and  A  to  whom  it  is 
given,  yet  it  shall  never  affect  the  bearer,  but  he  shall  have  his  whole  money." 


166  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

of  the  bona  fide  holder  of  a  bill  of  exchange  were  so  clearly- 
recognized  and  explained.1 

But  even  at  this  period,  when  it  was  only  a  bill  payable  to  A  or 
order  or  to  A  or  assigns  that  was  fully  transferable,  this  element  of 
negotiability  was  beginning  to  emerge.  It  was  being  reached  by 
two  different  routes.  In  the  first  place,  it  was  said  that  if  A  accepts 
a  bill  payable  to  B  or  order,  it  is  a  contract  by  A  to  pay  either  B  or 
any  assignee  in  whose  favour  B  makes  his  order.2  That  being  so, 
the  mere  fact  that  A  might  have  had  some  defence  to  an  action  on 
the  bill  if  B  had  sued  him,  will  not  allow  A  to  set  up  that  defence 
if  he  is  being  sued  by  B's  assignee.  Thus  in  Hussey  v.  Jacob 3  it 
was  said  by  Holt,  C.J.,  that  a  bill  of  exchange,  given  to  X  or  order 
for  a  gaming  debt,  and  void  under  the  statute  of  16  Charles  II.  c.  7, 
could  be  sued  on  by  X's  assignee,  at  any  rate  if  it  had  been  accepted 
after  the  assignment.4  In  the  second  place,  this  view  of  the  superior 
rights  of  the  assignee  was  assisted  by  the  theory  that  each  indorser 
of  a  bill  of  exchange  in  effect  draws  a  new  bill.5  It  follows  that  he 
is  liable  to  his  indorsee  irrespective  of  any  weakness  in  his  own 
position.  Thus  it  was  laid  down  in  Hill  v.  Lewis?  that,  if  a  bill 
was  drawn  without  words  of  negotiability,  the  drawer  was  not 
liable  to  an  indorsee  of  the  holder,  but  that  the  indorser  was  liable 
to  the  indorsee.  Moreover,  even  if  the  bill  had  been  forged,  the 
indorser  was  liable.7  In  both  cases  the  indorser  was  liable  on  the 
new  bill  which  he  had  drawn. 

These  cases  go  the  length  of  deciding  that  the  holder  of  a  bill  is 
not  liable  to  be  met  by  the  defences  which  would  be  valid  against  his 
transferor.  In  other  words,  the  bill  is  assignable  free  from  equities. 
But  suppose  that  the  bill  has  been  stolen,  and  that  the  holder  has 
acquired  through  the  thief — could  not  the  acceptor  refuse  to  pay, 
on  the  ground  that  the  holder  was  not  an  assign  at  all  ?  On  the 
principles  recognized  at  this  period  it  would  seem  that  he  ought 
to  have  been  able  to  refuse.  Yet  it  was  ruled  by  Holt  in  an 
anonymous  nisi  prius  case  that,  if  a  bank  bill  payable  to  A  or  bearer 
(i.e.  a  non-negotiable  bill)  was  lost,  and  was  found  by  X,  who  in- 
dorsed it  to  C,  A  could  sue  X  in  trover,  but  not  C,  "by  reason  of 
the  course  of  trade  which  creates  a  property  in  the  assignee  or 

1  As  for  instance  in  Peacock  v.  Rhodes  (1781)  2  Dougl.  at  p.  636. 

2  "  When  a  bill  is  payable  to  J.S.  or  order,  there  an  express  power  is  given  to  the 
party  to  assign,  and  the  indorsee  may  maintain  an  action,"  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1692) 
1  Salk.  125. 

3  (1697)  1  Comyns  4. 

4  "  If  such  a  note  was  given  to  the  winner  or  order,  and  the  winner  indorsed  it  to 
a  stranger  for  a  just  debt,  and  the  person  upon  whom  the  bill  was  drawn  accepts 
it  in  the  hands  of  the  stranger,  the  acceptor  would  be  liable,"  ibid  at  p.  6,  per  Holt, 
C.J. 

8  Above  163.  *  (1709)  1  Salk.  132. 

7  Lambert  v.  Pack  (1700)  1  Salk.  127. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        167 

bearer."1  In  other  words,  Holt  again  falls  back  on  the  custom 
of  the  merchants,  without  giving  any  explanation  of  the  rule  laid 
down.  In  fact,  as  I  have  said,  no  really  satisfactory  explanation 
could  be  given  till  the  negotiability  of  bearer  bills  was  recognized. 

(c)  In  a  bill  of  exchange  drawn  in  the  usual  form  the  drawer 
always  states  that  he  has  received  value.  Malynes  tells  us  that 
the  receipt  of  value  was  necessary  to  the  validity  of  bills  obliga- 
tory ; 2  and  the  forms  of  bills  of  exchange  show  that  this  is  also 
true  of  bills  of  exchange.  But,  from  an  early  date,  the  statement 
on  the  face  of  the  bill  that  value  had  been  received,  seems  to  have 
been  regarded  as  creating  a  presumption  in  favour  of  the  exist- 
ence of  a  consideration  ; 3  and  it  was  held  in  17 14  that  this  pre- 
sumption would  arise  whether  or  no  the  words  "value  received" 
were  present4  Such  consideration,  whether  proved  or  presumed 
to  exist,  will  give  the  holder  the  right  to  sue  the  acceptor  or  any 
of  the  other  parties  liable  on  the  bill.  But  it  is  now  settled  that 
if  it  can  be  shown  that  no  consideration  was  ever  given  as  between 
any  of  the  parties,  no  action  can  be  brought  on  the  bilL  It  is  not 
true  therefore  to  say  that  no  consideration  is  necessary  for  the 
validity  of  a  bill  of  exchange ;  but  it  is  true  to  say  that  there  are 
two  points  in  which  the  doctrine  of  consideration  is  applied  to  bills 
of  exchange  in  a  manner  different  from  that  in  which  it  is  applied 
to  other  contracts.  In  the  first  place,  the  burden  of  disproving  the 
presumption  that  consideration  has  been  given  is  on  the  defendant ; 
and,  in  the  second  place,  if  consideration  has  once  been  given 
for  the  drawing  of  the  bill  or  in  the  course  of  its  negotiation, 
the  presumption  that  consideration  has  been  given  is  irrebuttable.5 
It  follows  that  there  is  no  need  for  consideration  to  move  from 
the  holder  who  is  suing ;  and  this  exception  from  the  ordinary 
rule  was,  as  we  have  seen,  technically  justified  by  giving  the 
holder,  not  an  action  of  assumpsit,  to  succeed  in  which  he  would 
be  obliged  to  prove  a  consideration  moving  from  himself,  but  an 
action  on  the  case.6 

These  results  were  not  ascertained  till  after  this  period.  As 
we  have  seen,  the  courts  were  inclined  to  explain  the  rights  of 

1  (1699)  1  Salk.  126 ;  above  pp.  164,  165-166. 

2 Lex  Mercatoria,  74,  "the  civil  law  and  the  law  merchant  do  require  that  the 
bill  shall  declare  for  what  the  debt  groweth,  either  for  merchandize  or  for  money,  or 
any  other  lawful  consideration  "  ;  the  form  of  words  '*  current  money  for  merchandize," 
which  were  sometimes  found,  were  inserted  to  get  the  benefit  of  the  higher  rate  of 
interest  which  was  allowed  for  money  *'  in  the  course  of  traffic,"  ibid  74-75. 

s  "  If  the  drawer  mention  it  'for  value  received,''  then  he  is  chargeable  at  common 
law,"  Cramlington  v.  Evans  (1685)  1  Shower  5  per  Holt,  C.J. 

4Joscelinev.  Lassere  (1714)  Fortescue  281;  cp.  Hatch  v.  Trayes  (1840)  n  Ad. 
&  EL  702  ;  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  382,  383,  391,  392. 

*  Ibid  389. 

6  Brown  v.  London,  above  162  n.  4 ;  Hodges  v.  Steward  (1692)  1  Salk.  125,  and 
note. 


168  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  parties  by  reference  to  the  custom  of  the  merchants,  and  very 
rarely  attempted  to  explain  the  principles  upon  which  that  custom 
was  based.1  It  was  clear  that  the  doctrine  of  consideration  could 
not  be  applied  to  these  bills  in  the  same  manner  as  it  was  applied 
to  ordinary  simple  contracts.  For  instance,  an  acceptor  was  liable 
to  an  original  payee  or  an  indorsee,  though  no  consideration  had 
moved  from  such  payee  or  indorsee  to  the  acceptor.  Holt,  there- 
fore, and  many  of  the  other  judges,  came  to  the  conclusion  that 
the  bill  of  exchange  was  in  the  nature  of  a  contract  under  seal. 
Just  as  the  seal  made  the  agreement  valid  though  no  consideration 
was  present,  so  the  custom  of  the  merchants  made  the  acceptor, 
drawer,  or  indorser  liable.2  All  through  this  period  this  was 
the  prevailing  theory.  But  it  was  contrary  to  the  continental 
view  of  the  law  ; 3  contrary  to  the  view  taken  by  the  merchants  ; i 
and  inconsistent  with  the  ordinary  forms  of  bills  of  exchange.5 
The  modern  view  was  first  laid  down  in  connection  with  promissory 
notes.  We  shall  see  that  the  negotiability  of  these  notes  was  re- 
cognized by  a  statute  of  1704.6  In  1721  two  of  the  judges  ap- 
plied to  these  notes  the  doctrine  that  the  bill  was  in  the  nature  of 
a  contract  under  seal ;  but  the  other  two  judges  and  the  lord 
Chancellor  held  that  the  note  was  only  a  simple  contract ;  "  and 
notwithstanding  the  statute  says  that  the  money  shall  be  due 
and  payable  by  virtue  of  the  note,  that  only  makes  the  note  itself 
evidence  of  a  consideration  .  .  .  though  the  note  itself  be  evi- 
dence of  a  consideration,  yet  it  is  not  conclusive  evidence,  but 
turns  the  proof  on  the  defendant  to  show  that  there  was  no  con- 
sideration given." 7  This  view  was  accepted  by  the  courts  of 
common  law  in  relation  to  notes ; 8  and,  though  Lord  Mansfield 
decided  in  favour  of  the  opposite  view  in  Pillans  v.  Van  Mierop? 
the  decision  of  the  House  of  Lords  in  Rann  v.  Hughes™  made  it 
clear  that  a  bill  of  exchange  could  not,  merely  because  it  was  a 
written  contract,  be  in  the  same  position  as  a  contract  under  seal.11 
It  followed  that  the  principle  applicable  to  notes  was  applicable 
to  it. 

1  Thus  in  Cramlington  v.  Evans  (1685)  1  Shower  5,  Holt,  C.J.,  said  that  if  there  is 
no  mention  of  "  value  received,"  "then  you  must  come  upon  the  custom  of  the  mer- 
chants only"  ;  cp.  Woolvil  v.  Young  (1698)  5  Mod.  367. 

2  Thus  in  Clerke  v.  Martin  (1702)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  758,  Holt,  C.J.,  said  that  to 
allow  the  negotiability  of  promissory  notes  "  amounted  to  the  setting  up  of  a  new 
sort  of  specialty  "  ;  and  he  took  the  same  view  in  Cutting  v.  Williams  (1702)  7  Mod. 
at  p.  155  ;  cp.  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  383. 

3  Above  143.  4  Above  157;  Marius,  Advice  1. 
5  Above  152-153.  6  Below  173. 

7  Brown  v.  Marsh  (1721)  Gilb.  Eq.  Cases  154. 

8  Jefferies  v.  Austin  (1725)  1  Stra.  674. 

9  (1765)  3  Burr.  1663  at  p.  1669. 

10 (1797)  7  T.R.  350  note;  above  30. 
11  See  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  3S8-389. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        169 

(tit)  Some  peculiarities  in  the  English  law  as  to  bills  of  ex- 
change. 

By  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  the  law  as  to  bills  of 
exchange  was  administered  by  the  common  law  courts,  and  had 
become  part  of  the  common  law.  It  was  not  administered  in 
special  mercantile  tribunals,  as  was  generally  the  case  on  the  Con- 
tinent1 This  had  two  important  and  permanent  effects  on  the 
law.  In  the  first  place,  the  rule  that  the  bill  of  exchange  was 
only  valid  as  between  merchants  was  obsolete  by  the  end  of  the 
seventeenth  century.  In  the  case  of  Bromwich  v.  Lloyd'1  Treby, 
C.J.,  summed  up  the  result  of  the  cases  as  follows :  "  Bills  of  ex- 
change at  first  were  extended  only  to  merchant  strangers  trading 
with  English  merchants,  and  afterwards  to  inland  bills  between 
merchants  trading  with  one  another  here  in  England,  and  then  to 
all  traders  and  business  men,  and  lastly  to  all  persons  whether 
traders  or  not."  The  first  stage  is  represented  in  the  work  of 
Malynes,  the  second  in  the  Tract  of  Marius,  and  the  third  is  the 
result  of  the  cases  decided  in  the  last  quarter  of  the  seventeenth 
century.  In  the  second  place,  as  the  bill  of  exchange  ceased  to 
be  used  exclusively  by  traders,  it  came  to  perform  a  function  other 
than  that  of  enabling  a  person  to  pay  a  debt  in  a  distant  place. 
The  rule  still  prevailing  in  France  that  "  the  place  where  a  bill  is 
drawn  must  be  so  far  distant  from  the  place  where  it  is  payable 
that  there  may  be  a  possible  rate  of  exchange  between  the  two," 3 
was  disappearing  as  early  as  1697.4  The  result  has  been  that  "in 
England  bills  have  developed  into  a  perfectly  flexible  paper  cur- 
rency. In  France  a  bill  represents  a  trade  transaction  ;  in  England 
it  is  merely  an  instrument  of  credit.  English  law  gives  full  play 
to  the  system  of  accommodation  paper ;  French  law  endeavours 
to  stamp  it  out."  5  We  have  seen  that  even  in  France  it  is  re- 
cognized as  performing  some  of  the  functions  of  a  paper  currency ; 6 
but  in  England  this  function  has  been  much  more  completely 
worked  out,  largely  because  these  bills  have  not  been  confined  to 
their  original  purpose  of  providing  a  method  of  avoiding  the 
dangers  of  a  physical  transport  of  money.7  This  difference  was 
not  fully  apparent  at  the  end  of  this  period.  Although  a  bill  was 
coming  to  be  regarded  as  a  species  of  currency,  it  was  quite  clearly 

1  Vol.  v  148-154.  a  (l697)  2  Lut.  1585. 

'Chalmers,  Bills  of  Exchange  (7th  ed.).  Introd.  lxii. 

*  The  facts  of  Hussy  v.  Jacob,  1  Comyns  4,  make  this  clear. 

5  Chalmers,  op.  cit.  lxi-lxii. 

6  Above  145  ;  cp.  Chalmers,  op.  cit  lxi.  note. 

7  As  early  as  1720  this  aspect  of  the  bill  of  exchange  was  recognized  in  the  case 
of  Bom  ley  v.  Frazier,  1  Stra.  441;  the  court  there  said,  "the  design  of  the  law  of 
merchants  in  distinguishing  these  from  all  other  contracts,  by  making  them  assign- 
able, was  for  the  convenience  of  commerce,  that  they  might  pass  from  hand  to  hand 
in  the  way  of  trade,  in  the  same  manner  as  if  they  were  specie." 


170  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

settled  that  it  was  not  an  absolute  payment,  unless  the  creditor 
chose  to  take  it  as  such.  It  operated  as  a  payment  only  if  it  was 
met  at  maturity;1  and  this  is  still  the  law.2  But  the  root  of  the 
difference  between  the  English  and  the  continental  developments 
was  present ;  and  if  we  look  back  at  the  law  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  present  day  we  can  clearly  see  its  beginnings. 

Similarly  the  principles  which  underlie  the  various  elements 
which  go  to  make  up  the  idea  of  negotiability  had  not  been  as  yet 
clearly  worked  out.  These  various  elements  were  in  many  cases 
justified  by  a  reference  to  the  custom  of  the  merchants  without 
being  explained.  But  the  underlying  principles  were  often  very 
near  to  the  mind  of  the  judges,  and  only  awaited  a  clear  statement. 
We  shall  now  see  that  the  task  of  making  this  statement  in  the 
following  century,  was  materially  helped  by  the  somewhat  peculiar 
history  of  the  recognition  of  the  negotiable  character  of  the  pro- 
missory note. 

(3)   The  promissory  note? 

In  England,  as  abroad,  the  development  of  the  negotiable 
character  of  the  bill  of  exchange  reacted  upon  the  legal  position 
of  the  note,  or  bill  obligatory,  payable  to  bearer.4  We  have  seen 
that  the  common  law,  in  the  sixteenth  and  early  part  of  the 
seventeenth  centuries,  did  not  recognize  the  assignability  which 
these  instruments  possessed  according  to  the  customs  prevailing 
amongst  the  merchants.5  But  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth 
century  many  of  these  mercantile  customs  had  become  part  of  the 
common  law.6  The  assignability  of  bills  of  exchange  payable  to 
order  was  fully  recognized ; 7  and  many  of  the  other  rules  relating 
to  them  were  so  contrary  to  the  ordinary  principles  of  the  common 
law,  that  they  could  only  be  justified  by  a  reference  to  mercantile 
custom.  Could  not  mercantile  custom  do  for  these  notes  what  it 
had  done  for  the  bill  of  exchange  ? 

Cases  decided  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century 
show  that  the  lawyers  were  inclined  to  answer  this  question  in  the 

1  Ward  v.  Evans  (1702)  2  Ld.  Raym.  928,  this  was  ruled  as  to  notes ;  Holt,  C.J. 
said,  "  I  am  of  opinion  and  always  was  (notwithstanding  the  noise  and  cry  that  it  is 
the  use  of  Lombard  Street,  as  if  the  contrary  opinion  would  blow  up  Lombard  Street) 
that  the  acceptance  of  such  a  note  is  not  actual  payment  .  .  .  when  such  a  note  is 
given  in  payment,  it  is  always  intended  to  be  taken  under  this  condition,  to  be  pay- 
ment if  the  money  be  paid  thereon  in  convenient  time";  in  Hill  v.  Lewis  (1709) 
Holt,  C.J.,  seems  to  lay  down  the  same  rule  as  to  bills  of  exchange,  though  the  case 
concerned  notes. 

2  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  389-391 ;  of  course  it  is  otherwise  if  the  instrument  is  accepted 
in  full  discharge,  Vernon  v.  Boverie  (1683)  2  Shower  296. 

3  On  this  topic  see  generally  Cranch,  Promissory  Notes  before  and  after  Lord 
Holt,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  72-94;  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  363-372,  383-392. 

4  Above  125-126.  8  Above  150-151. 
"Above  160-161.                                        7  Above  163-164. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        171 

affirmative.1  Indeed  it  is  clear,  as  Lord  Mansfield  once  com- 
plained,2 that  they  did  not  distinguish  between  the  inland  bill  and 
the  promissory  note.  Both  are  often  called  bills  of  exchange  in 
the  pleadings 3  and  in  the  reports  ; 4  and  the  bill  introduced  into  the 
House  of  Lords  to  make  bills  of  debt  transferable,  appears  to  have 
taken  the  view  that  inland  bills  of  exchange  were  governed  by 
the  same  rules  as  bills  of  debt,  since  it  proposed  to  make  them 
transferable  like  foreign  bills  of  exchange.5  In  one  important 
respect,  indeed,  they  closely  resembled  one  another,  and  differed 
from  the  outland  bill.  Upon  neither  was  a  protest  necessary  as 
a  condition  of  recovery  against  the  drawer,  till  an  Act  passed  in 
1698  required  a  protest  in  the  event  of  the  non-payment  of  an 
inland  bill  of  exchange.6  In  fact,  it  was  not  till  Holt's  campaign 
against  promissory  notes,  and  the  passing  of  the  statute  of  1704, 
that  the  distinction  was  clearly  drawn.7  This  being  so,  we  are  not 
surprised  to  find  that  the  development  of  the  law  relating  to  pro- 
missory notes  is  very  closely  connected  with  the  development  of  the 
law  relating  to  bills  of  exchange.  Thus  a  note  payable  to  X  or 
order  was  treated  as  assignable  by  indorsement  and  delivery,  while 
a  note  payable  to  X  or  bearer  was,  after  some  hesitation,8  treated 
like  a  bill  to  bearer,  as  not  assignable.9 

1  Shelden  v.  Hentley  (1680)  2  Shower,  161 — a  bearer  allowed  to  sue  on  a  note 
under  seal  promising  to  pay  the  bearer  who  delivered  the  note ;  Williams  v.  Williams 
(1692)  Carth.  269 ;  S.C.  3  Salk.  68  sub  nomine  William  v.  Field ;  Hawkins  v.  Cardy 
(1699)  Carth.  466,  1  Ld.  Raym.  360 ;  in  the  latter  report  the  document  is  errone- 
ously called  a  bill  of  exchange ;  for  an  account  of  all  these  cases  see  Cranch,  op.  cit. 
83-87. 

2  Grant  v.  Vaughan  (1764)  3  Burr,  at  p.  1525 — "  Upon  looking  into  the  reports  of 
the  cases  on  this  head,  in  the  times  of  King  William  the  Third  and  Queen  Anne,  it 
is  difficult  to  discover  by  them,  when  the  question  arises  upon  a  bill  and  when  upon 
a  note  :  for  the  reporters  do  not  express  themselves  with  sufficient  precision,  but  use 
the  words  ■  note  '  and  '  bill '  promiscuously." 

3  See  e.g.  Brownlow,  Declarations  (3rd  ed.)  266-267 — "  Whereas  also  there  is, 
and  from  the  time  of  the  contrary  whereof  the  memory  of  man  is  not  extant  there 
hath  been  such  a  custome  within  the  kingdome  of  the  Lord  the  king  now  of  Eng- 
land betweene  English  merchants  or  forrainers  and  their  factors  or  servants,  used 
and  approved,  that  if  any  merchant  or  merchants  aforesaid,  or  their  factors  or  ser- 
vants, being  in  parts  beyond  sea,  without  the  aforesaid  kingdom  of  England,  should 
deliver  to  any  person,  in  the  same  parts  beyond  sea  being,  any  sum  of  moneyes  to 
be  paid  by  any  person  in  the  same  kingdome  of  England  being  by  bill  or  note  of 
exchange  thereof  made,  [and  such  person]  should  so  accept  and  subscribe,  from  the 
whole  time  aforesaid,  [he]  was  chargeable  and  hath  been  accustomed  to  be  charge- 
able to  pay  the  said  sum  of  money  to  such  person  as  by  the  same  bill  or  note  of 
Exchange  should  be  limited  and  expressed  to  be  paid." 

4  Hawkins  v.  Cardy  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  360  ;  Cranch,  op.  cit.  87  ;  Street,  op.  cit. 
H369. 

5  Above  151  n.  1 ;  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  8th  Rep.  137. 

6  Brough  v.  Parkins  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  992 ;  9, 10  William  III.  c.  17  ;  the  statute 
was  defective  in  that  it  did  not  provide  for  a  protest  in  case  of  non-acceptance  ;  this 
was  remedied  by  3,  4  Anne,  c.  g,  §  4. 

7  Below  172-173.  8  Shelden  v.  Hentley  (16S1)  2  Shower,  161. 

9  Horton  v.  Coggs  (1692)  3  Lev.  299 — "After  a  verdict  for  the  plaintiff  it  was 
moved  in  arrest  of  judgment,  that  this  custom  to  pay  to  the  bearer  was  too  general ; 
for  perhaps  the  goldsmith  before  notice  by  the  bearer  had  paid  it  to  Barlow  himself 


172  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

During  the  later  years  of  the  seventeenth  century  cases  turning 
upon  these  notes  came  with  increasing  frequency  before  the  courts. 
This  was  no  doubt  due  to  the  growth  of  depositing  money  with  the 
goldsmiths,  who  at  this  period  were  beginning  to  do  the  business  of 
bankers.1  They  issued  these  notes  promising  to  pay  the  sum  de- 
posited, sometimes  to  a  payee  or  bearer,  sometimes  to  a  payee  or 
order.  In  1704  Holt,  C.J.  said  that  the  merchants  agreed  that 
they  had  been  in  use  for  some  thirty  years  ;  and  that  he  remembered 
when  actions  upon  them  first  began  to  be  brought.2  But  we  have 
seen  that  in  mercantile  practice  similar  notes  were  much  older.3 
However,  there  is  a  sense  in  which  Holt's  statement  is  true ;  their 
use  by  the  goldsmiths,  and  their  appearance  in  courts  of  common 
law,  were  not  much  older.4 

Down  to  the  year  1700  the  history  of  these  notes  had  been 
uneventful.  They  were  very  generally  confused  with  inland  bills 
of  exchange ;  and  it  seemed  as  if  they  would  silently  assume  the 
same  negotiable  character  as  these  bills.5  But  in  that  year,  in  the 
case  of  Clerke  v.  Martin*  Holt,  C.J.  decided  that  a  note  payable 
to  X  or  order  was  not  a  bill  of  exchange,  and  was  therefore  not  ne- 
gotiable. He  said,  "  that  this  note  could  not  be  a  bill  of  exchange, 
that  the  maintaining  of  these  actions  upon  such  notes  were  innova- 
tions upon  rules  of  the  common  law ;  and  that  it  amounted  to  the 
setting  up  a  new  sort  of  specialty,  unknown  to  the  common  law, 
and  invented  in  Lombard  Street,  which  attempted  in  these  matters 
of  bills  of  exchange  to  give  laws  to  Westminster  Hall.  That  the 
continuing  to  declare  upon  these  notes  upon  the  custom  of  merchants 

(which  at  the  Bar  was  said  to  be  the  truth  of  the  case).  And  of  that  opinion  after 
divers  motions  were  Pollexfen,  Powell,  and  Rokesby  .  .  .  though  upon  the  trial  of 
the  cause  before  Pollexfen  at  the  Guildhall  he  then  held  the  action  well  lay,  this 
matter  having  been  objected  at  the  said  trial  "  ;  Nicholson  v.  Sedgwick  (1698)  1  Ld. 
Raym.  180  ;  but,  according  to  the  report  of  Nicholson  v.  Sedgwick,  in  3  Salk.  67,  it 
was  admitted  that  a  note  payable  to  order  was  negotiable  ;  and  the  same  decision  was 
come  to  in  Carter  v.  Palmer  (1701)  12  Mod.  380,  Holt  doubting ;  but  it  would  seem 
from  Crawley  v.  Crowther  (1702)  2  Freeman,  Cases  in  Chy.,  at  p.  258,  that  the  com- 
mon law  view  as  to  a  bearer  instrument  was  not  followed  in  the  court  of  Chancery ; 
see  above  164  n.  5,  165. 

1  Below  185-186. 

2  Buller  v.  Crips,  6  Mod.  29,  30 — "  At  another  day,  Holt,  C.J.  declared  that  .  .  .  two 
of  the  most  famous  merchants  in  London  .  .  .  had  told  him,  it  was  very  frequent  with 
them  to  make  such  notes,  and  that  they  looked  upon  them  as  bills  of  exchange,  and 
that  they  had  been  used  for  a  matter  of  thirty  years,  and  that  not  only  notes  but  bonds 
for  money  were  transferred  frequently,  and  indorsed  as  bills  0/  exchange." 

3  Above  147-150. 

4  Dudley  North  was  away  from  England  between  1661  and  1680;  his  brother  tells 
us,  Lives  of  the  Norths,  ii  174,  that,  "  He  found  divers  usages  in  London  very  different 
from  what  had  been  practised  in  his  time  there  ...  as  first  touching  their  running 
cash,  which,  by  almost  all  sorts  of  merchants,  was  slid  into  goldsmiths'  hands ;  and 
they  themselves  paid  and  received  only  by  bills  ;  as  if  all  their  dealings  were  in  banco. 
He  counted  this  a  foolish  lazy  method,  and  obnoxious  to  great  accidents  ;  and  he  never 
could  bring  himself  wholly  to  comply  with  it." 

5  See  the  cases  cited  above  171  nn.  1  and  4.  62  Ld.  Raym.  757. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        173 

proceeded  from  obstinacy  and  opinionativeness,  since  he  had  always 
expressed  his  opinion  against  them,  and  since  there  was  so  easy  a 
method,  as  to  declare  upon  a  general  indebitatus  assumpsit  for 
money  lent"  This  case,  as  Holt  himself  admitted,  caused  a  con- 
siderable outcry  in  the  mercantile  world.1  But  the  decision  was 
upheld  in  three  subsequent  cases ; 2  and  the  merchants  were  obliged 
to  get  an  Act  passed  to  reverse  them.3 

The  Act  in  substance  provides  that  all  notes  in  writing,  made 
and  signed  by  any  person,  whereby  he  promises  to  pay  to  any  other 
person  or  his  order  or  to  any  person  or  bearer,  shall  be  assignable 
and  indorsable  over  in  the  same  manner  and  with  the  same  legal 
effect  as  if  they  were  inland  bills  of  exchange4  This  was  inter- 
preted to  mean  that  all  such  notes,  whether  payable  to  A  simply,  or 
to  A  or  order,  to  A  or  bearer,  were  made  negotiable.5 

Holt's  treatment  of  these  promissory  notes,  and  the  reversal  of 
his  views  by  statute,  raise  two  interesting  questions.  Firstly,  was 
there  any  justification  for  his  views  ?  and  secondly,  what  has  been 
the  effect  of  the  statute  upon  the  law  as  to  negotiable  instruments  ? 

(i)  Distinguished  lawyers  of  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth 
centuries,6  and  legal  historians  of  our  own  days,7  have  generally 
maintained  that  Holt's  views  were  merely  wrong-headed ;  that 
they  were  historically  false,  and  wholly  opposed  to  the  current  of 
authority  in  his  own  time  There  is  much  to  be  said  for  this 
view.  Firstly,  from  an  early  period  notes  payable  to  bearer  were 
recognized  abroad,  and  possibly  in  England,  as  assignable  by 
mercantile  custom.  They  were  certainly  known  to  the  English 
merchants  from  the  sixteenth  century  onwards.8  Secondly,  there 
are  one  or  two  decisions  which  recognized  the  existing  mercantile 
custom,  and  treated  these  notes  as  being  on  precisely  the  same 

1  Buller  v.  Crips  (1704)  6  Mod.  at  p.  30. 

2  Potter  v.  Pearson,  2  Ld.  Raym.  759  ;  Buller  v.  Crips,  6  Mod.  29 ;  Cutting  v. 
Williams,  7  Mod.  155  ;  though  it  was  not  followed  in  the  Chancery,  above  171  n.  9. 

'3,  4  Anne  c.  9;  the  bill  was  presented  27  Jan.,  1703,  Commons'  Journals  xiv. 
312  ;  it  was  committed  Feb.  12.  ibid  335,  and  reached  its  third  reading  Feb.  2,  1704, 
ibid  508 ;  in  the  Lords  it  was  appointed  to  be  read  a  second  time  Feb.  8,  1704,  and 
Holt,  C.J.,  was  ordered  to  attend,  Lords'  Journals  xvi.  653  ;  probably  he  was  respon- 
sible for  the  additions  made  by  the  Lords,  which  in  substance  correspond  to  §§  5,  7, 
and  9  of  the  Act ;  these  amendments  were  agreed  to  by  the  Lords  on  Feb.  15,  ibid 
664 ;  the  Commons  accepted  them  and  made  further  amendments  on  Feb.  22,  Commons' 
Journals  xiv  546,  674,  which  the  Lords  agreed  to  on  the  26th,  ibid  676. 

'Burchell  v.  Slocock  (1728)  2  Ld.  Raym.  1545;  but  see  Wain  v.  Bailey  (1839) 
10  Ad.  and  E.  616  where  it  was  held  that  a  plaintiff  could  recover  on  a  lost  note  payable 
to  himself  simply ;  it  has  been  assumed  that  this  means  that  such  notes  were  not 
negotiable  see  Thairlwall  v.  G.N.R.  [1910]  2  K.B.  at  p.  519 ;  but  this  seems  contrary  to 
the  Act  of  Anne  and  the  decision  of  Burchell  v.  Slocock ;  but  the  point  now  has  only  an 
academic  interest  owing  to  the  provisions  of  the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act,  1882,  above 
156  n.  5. 

•  Grant  v.  Vaughan  (1764)  1  W.  Black  at  p.  487,  per  Ld.  Mansfield,  C.J. ;  Good- 
win v.  Robarts  (1875)  L.R.  10  Ex.  at  p.  349,  per  Cockburn,  C.J. 

7  Cranch,  op.  cit  89-93  J  Street,  op.  cit  ii.  386.  8  Above  116,  147-150. 


174  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

footing  as  inland  bills  of  exchange.1  Thirdly,  there  is  certainly 
one  case  in  which  Holt  himself  recognized  the  negotiability  of  bank 
bills.2  At  the  same  time  it  is  generally  admitted  that  it  is  chiefly 
to  Holt's  decisions  that  we  must  look  for  the  beginnings  of  the 
modern  law  as  to  negotiable  instruments.3  Why  then  should  a 
man  who  was  quite  alive  to  the  importance  of  commercial  law, 
who  by  his  decisions  did  much  to  settle  the  principles  of  many 
branches  of  that  law,  have  gone  out  of  his  way  to  give  decisions 
which  were  both  bad  in  law,  and  injurious  to  the  interests  of  the 
merchants  ? 

It  seems  to  me  that  Holt's  decisions  rested  upon  two  chief 
grounds.  In  the  first  place,  he  had  perceived,  what  most  of  his 
brother  lawyers  had  not  perceived,  that  there  was  a  difference 
between  an  inland  bill  of  exchange  and  a  promissory  note.4  It 
may  be  that  the  statute  of  1698,  which  required  a  protest  in  case 
of  the  non-payment  by  the  acceptor  of  an  inland  bill  of  exchange, 
had  made  the  difference  clearer.5  But,  whether  this  be  so  or  not, 
it  is  clear  that  Holt  considered  that  assignability  was  the  peculiar 
property  of  the  bill  of  exchange  annexed  to  it  by  law  ;  that  these 
notes  were  not  bills  of  exchange ;  and  that  this  was  a  mere  attempt 
on  the  part  of  the  "goldsmiths  in  Lombard  Street  ...  to  make 
a  law  to  bind  all  those  that  did  deal  with  them."  6  He  pointed 
out  that  the  same  object  could  be  substantially  effected  by  a  bill 
of  exchange  drawn  between  two  persons.  In  Buller  v.  Crips  he 
said  : 7  "  Indeed  I  agree  a  bill  of  exchange  may  be  made  between 
two  persons  without  a  third  ;  and  if  there  be  such  a  necessity  of 
dealing  that  way,  why  do  not  dealers  use  that  way  which  is  legal  ? 
.  .  .  as,  if  A  has  money  to  lodge  in  B's  hands,  and  would  have  a 
negotiable  note  for  it,  it  is  only  saying  thus  :   '  Mr.  B.  pay  me,  or 

1  Above  171. 

2  (1698)  Anon.  1  Salk.  126  ;  S.C.  1  Ld.  Raym.  738  ;  I  think  it  probable  that  the 
bank  notes  or  bills  in  this  case  were  either  notes  drawn  payable  to  order  in  the  form  of 
bills  of  exchange,  which  Holt  admitted  to  be  negotiable  ;  or  possibly  they  were  bank 
of  England  bills ;  5,  6  William  and  Mary,  c.  20,  §  28,  had  provided  for  the  issue  of 
Bills  by  the  Bank  which  could  be  assigned  indefinitely  by  indorsement  and  delivery, 
and  Holt  would  no  doubt  have  regarded  these  bills  as  being  in  the  same  position 
as  bills  of  exchange ;  it  was  the  ordinary  notes  or  bills  of  the  goldsmiths,  which 
merely  acknowledged  the  receipt  of  money  and  promised  to  pay  it,  which  were  hit  by 
his  decisions  ;  see  Buller  v.  Crips  (1704)  6  Mod.  29. 

3  "  Though  radically  reactionary  in  dealing  with  promissory  notes,  in  other  respects 
he  displayed  much  learning  and  judgment  in  deciding  rights  arising  out  of  commercial 
transactions,  and  the  law  of  bills  is  greatly  indebted  to  him,"  Street,  op.  cit.  ii  378  ;  cp. 
Smith's  Mercantile  Law  (tith  ed.),  Introd.  lxxxii,  n. ;  and  see  vol.  vi  519-522. 

4  Compare  his  views  as  to  the  restricted  competency  of  Indebitatus  Assumpsit, 
which  arose  from  his  perception  of  the  difference  between  contract  and  quasi-contract, 
above  90-91. 

8  Above  171 ;  that  Holt  was  a  good  deal  interested  in  this  branch  of  the  law  can 
be  seen  from  the  amendments  made  by  the  House  of  Lords  to  the  Act  of  3,  4,  Anne, 
c.  9,  which  were  probably  suggested  by  him  ;  above  173  n.  3. 

6  Buller  v.  Crips  (1704)  6  Mod.  29.  7  6  Mod.  at  p.  30. 


THE  ENGLISH  DEVELOPMENT        175 

order,  so  much  money  value  to  yourself  ;  and  signing  this,  and  B 
accepting  it :  or  he  may  take  the  common  note  and  say  thus  :  '  for 
value  received  pay  me  (or  indorsee)  so  much  ' ;  and  good."  The 
outcry  of  the  merchants  he  considered  to  be  mere  "  opinionative- 
ness "  seeing  that  they  could  do  what  they  wanted  by  a  slight 
variation  in  the  form  of  their  instruments.1  In  the  second  place, 
Holt  considered  that  a  bill  of  exchange  was  a  specialty  ; 2  that  no 
set  of  men  could  give  to  what  was  a  simple  contract  the  character- 
istics of  a  specialty  ;  and  that  the  attempt  to  do  so,  if  acquiesced 
in,  would  mean  that  "  Lombard  Street  would  give  the  laws  to 
Westminster  Hall."  3  The  merchants  had,  as  we  have  seen,  told 
him  that  not  only  notes  but  "bonds  for  money"  were  treated  by 
them  as  bills  of  exchange ; 4  and  there  is  some  evidence  that  they 
considered  that  a  policy  of  insurance,  when  indorsed  and  transferred, 
"thereby  became  as  good  as  a  bill  of  exchange  is."5  His  view, 
therefore,  was  that  ignorant  laymen,  without  any  real  justification, 
were  attempting  to  upset  the  true  legal  principle,  which  he  had 
discovered,  that  the  promissory  note  was  a  contract  of  a  very 
different  nature  from  the  bill  of  exchange.  They  were  persisting 
in  their  view,  although  they  could  have  effected  all  their  purposes 
by  means  of  a  bill  of  exchange  Such  opposition  aroused  both  his 
personal  and  his  professional  pride,  and  fully  accounts  for  the 
temper  which  he  displayed  on  this  occasion. 

We  have  seen  that  Holt's  view  that  the  bill  of  exchange  was 
a  specialty  (though  held  by  many  common  lawyers)  was  eventu- 
ally adjudged  to  be  erroneous.6  But  it  seems  to  me  that  there 
was  a  good  deal  to  be  said  in  favour  of  the  other  ground  upon 
which  he  rested  his  decision.  There  is  no  doubt  that  a  promis- 
sory note  is  an  instrument  of  a  different  nature  from  a  bill  of 
exchange.  These  promissory  notes  were  of  comparatively  recent 
introduction  into  the  common  law.  It  is  true  that  they  had  been 
long  familiar  to  the  merchants.  But  it  would  seem  that  they  had 
only  come  into  extensive  use  within  the  last  thirty  years  ;  '  and 
they  had  assumed  their  negotiable  characteristics  in  the  common 
law  courts  under  cover  of  a  false  analogy  to  the  inland  bill  of 
exchange.  It  followed  that,  when  the  falsity  of  that  analogy 
had  been  demonstrated,  their  supposed  negotiable  character  dis- 
appeared. 

There  was  technical  force  in  this  argument — especially  in  the 
seventeenth  century.  Its  fallacy  lay  in  the  assumption  that  even 
the  most  correct  technical  reasoning  could  stop  the  development 

1  Clerke  v.  Martin  (1702)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  758.  2  Above  168. 

3  Clerke  v.  Martin  (1702)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  758.  4  Above  172  n.  2. 

5  See  Davenant  v.  Midy  (1695-1696)  House  of  Lords,  MSS.  (N.S.)  ii  196  no.  1009. 

"Above  168.  7  Above  172. 


176  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

of  the  new  machinery  rendered  necessary  by  the  new  needs  of  an 
expanding  trade.  On  the  contrary,  it  was  clear  from  the  history 
of  the  bill  of  exchange  that  the  law  must  adapt  its  technical  rules 
to  that  machinery.  But,  once  that  adaptation  had  been  made, 
Holt  considered  that  the  law  had  gone  far  enough.  One  form  of 
negotiable  instrument  should  suffice.  Even  in  the  nineteenth 
century  substantially  similar  views  have  been  held  by  dis- 
tinguished judges.1  At  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century 
the  Legislature  was  obliged  to  intervene  to  correct  this  error :  in 
the  nineteenth  and  twentieth  centuries  the  courts  themselves  have 
recognized  its  fallacy,  and  corrected  it.2 

(2)  I  have  already  indicated  the  broad  result  of  the  statute — 
Holt's  judgments  were  reversed,  and  promissory  notes  were  made 
negotiable.  This  episode  taught  the  courts  that  they  could  not 
wholly  ignore  approved  mercantile  custom  ;  that  they  must  adapt 
their  rules  to  such  customs  ;  that  in  fact  there  were  cases  in  which 
"  Lombard  Street  must  be  allowed  to  give  laws  to  Westminster 
Hall."  And  the  eighteenth  century  was  to  show  that  the  courts 
had  learned  that  lesson.  It  was  a  salutary  and  a  necessary 
lesson  ;  and,  if  it  had  not  been  learned,  it  is  difficult  to  see  how  a 
non-mercantile  set  of  tribunals  could  have  made  commercial  law 
for  the  greatest  commercial  nation  of  modern  times.  Further,  it 
had  a  beneficial  result  on  the  development  of  the  law  of  negoti- 
able instruments.  Notes  to  bearer  were  declared  to  be  negotiable 
by  the  statute ;  and  the  case  of  Grant  v.  Vaughan 3  shows  that 
the  courts  were  assisted  in  coming  to  the  conclusion  that  a  bill  to 
bearer  was  negotiable,  by  a  chain  of  reasoning  (historically  some- 
what fallacious)  based  upon  this  statute.  We  have  seen  that  it 
was  not  till  the  independent  rights  of  the  bearer  were  recognized, 
that  the  most  essential  of  all  the  elements  of  negotiability — the 
absolute  title  of  the  bona  fide  holder  for  value — could  clearly 
emerge.4 

It  is  not  till  the  following  period  that  this  and  other  principles 
underlying  the  law  as  to  negotiable  instruments  were  clearly 
ascertained.  In  this  period  a  good  start  had  been  made  ;  but  it 
was  only  a  start.  The  united  efforts  of  several  generations  both 
of  merchants  and  lawyers  were  needed  before  the  common  law 
attained  an  adequate  body  of  doctrine  upon  this,  and  upon  many 
other  branches  of  commercial  law. 

1  Crouch  v.  Credit  Foncier  (1873)  L.R.  8  Q.B.  at  p.  386, /><;>•  Blackburn,  J. 

2  Goodwin  v.  Robarts  (1875)  L.R.  10  Ex.  337 ;  Bechuanaland  Exploration  Co. 
v.  London  Trading  Bank  [1898]  2  Q.B.  658;  Edelstein  v.  Schuler  [1902]  2  K.B. 
144. 

s(i764)  3  Burr.  1516 ;  see  especially  the  judgment  of  Wilmot,  J.,  at  pp.  1527- 
1528. 

4  Above  165-166. 


BANKING  177 

We  must  now  turn  to  the  history  of  the  closely  allied  topic  of 
Banking. 

§  3.  Banking 

It  was  at  one  time  thought  that  the  earliest  bank  known  to 
modern  history  was  the  bank  of  Venice,  and  that  it  was  founded 
about  the  year  1170  to  finance  a  state  debt  But  this  opinion 
has  been  definitely  disproved  by  the  researches  of  Lattes  and 
Ferrara.1  They  show  that  it  was  the  catnpsores,  or  money- 
changers, who  were  the  earliest  bankers ;  and  that  the  same  set 
of  economic  causes  which  gave  rise  to  the  bill  of  exchange,  gave 
rise  also  to  the  institution  of  banking.2 

We  have  seen  that  money  was  entrusted  to  these  catnpsores  for 
purposes  of  transmission,  and  that,  by  means  of  the  machinery  of 
the  bill  of  exchange,  both  the  risks  of  transport 3  and  the  risk  of 
receiving  in  payment  defective  or  counterfeit  coins  were  avoided.4 
It  was  not  long  before  their  business  extended  itself  in  different 
directions.  On  the  one  hand,  a  merchant  who  had  begun  by  en- 
trusting a  particular  sum  to  a  money-changer  for  purposes  of 
transmission  in  a  particular  transaction,  found  it  convenient  to 
keep  with  him  a  sum  on  which  he  could  draw  whenever  he  needed 
to  transmit  money ;  and  others,  besides  merchants,  found  it  con- 
venient to  deposit  money  with  such  a  person  for  safe  custody. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  money-changer  was  only  too  glad  to  get 
this  money  into  his  hands,  and  was  willing  to  pay  something  to 
get  it.  He  could  lend  it  at  remunerative  rates  to  needy  princes 
or  to  merchants.  Thus  the  Italian  money-changers  gradually 
replaced  the  Jews  as  the  financiers  of  Europe.5  The  Caorsini, 
for  instance,  were  the  Pope's  collectors ;  and  they  made  large 
profits  by  lending  the  sums  in  their  hands  to  needy  borrowers.6 
The  English  kings  were  large  borrowers  from  various  Italian 
houses;"  and  Edward  III.,  by  his  refusal  to  repay  the  money 

*For  an  account  of  their  work  see  C.  F.  Dunbar,  Economic  Essays  143  seqq. 

*  Above  128-130.  3  Ibid. 

*"  The  notion  of  its  being  a  prime  business  of  a  bank  to  give  good  coin  has 
passed  out  of  men's  memories  ;  but  wherever  it  is  felt  there  is  no  want  of  business 
more  keen  and  urgent,"  Bagehot,  Lombard  Street,  81.  The  establishment  of  some 
state  banks,  eg.  Venice  and  Amsterdam,  was  caused  primarily  by  the  fact  that  this 
business  was  not  satisfactorily  done  by  the  private  bankers,  below  180-181. 

s  The  Italian  bankers  in  England  and  their  loans  to  Edward  I.  and  Edward  II., 
Historical  Essays  (edited  by  T.  F.  Tout  and  J.  Tait),  137-167;  see  ibid  pp.  143-153 
for  instances  of  loans  to  Edward  I.  on  the  security  of  the  customs. 

'  Mat.  Par.,  Chron.  Mai.  (R.S.)  iii.  331-332,  s.a.  1235  "  Eodemque  anno,  episco- 
pus  Londoniensis  Rogerus  .  .  .  cum  intellexisset  hos  Caursinos  usuras  sine  erube- 
scentia  palam  frequentare  vitamque  spurcissimam  deducere,  viros  religiosos  varus 
iniuriis  fatigare,  pecuniamque  argumentose  coacervare,  et  multos  iuga  eorum  coactos 
subire,  commotus  est  et  iratus  "  ;  he  excommunicated  them,  but  they  had  no  difficulty 
in  getting  protection  from  their  employer  the  Pope, 

7  Above  n.  5. 

VOL.  VIII.— 12 


178  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

which  he  had  thus  borrowed,  ruined  the  Peruzzi  and  the  Bardi  of 
Florence.1 

This  development  had  taken  place  in  Venice,  and  probably 
also  in  the  other  commercial  cities  in  Italy,  by  the  first  half  of  the 
fourteenth  century.  "  It  is  tolerably  clear,"  says  Dunbar,2  "that 
private  banking  in  Venice  began  as  an  adjunct  of  the  business  of 
the  catnpsores  or  dealers  in  foreign  moneys.  In  a  city  having  a 
great  and  varied  trade  with  many  countries,  these  dealers  neces- 
sarily held  an  important  place.  ...  As  early  as  1270  it  was 
deemed  necessary  to  require  them  to  give  security  to  the  govern- 
ment as  the  condition  of  carrying  on  their  business,  but  it  is  not 
shown  that  they  were  then  receiving  deposits.  In  an  Act  of 
September  24,  1318,  however,  entitled  '  Bancherii  scriptae  dent 
plegiarias  consulibus,'  the  receipt  of  deposits  by  the  campsores  is 
recognized  as  an  existing  practice,  and  provision  is  made  for 
better  security  for  the  benefit  of  the  depositors.  Whether  the 
title  of  this  Act  is  contemporary  or  not,  its  text  shows  that  some- 
where between  1270  and  13 18  the  money-changers  of  Venice 
were  becoming  bankers,  by  a  method  similar  to  that  by  which  the 
same  class  of  men  at  Amsterdam  a  couple  of  centuries  later,  and 
later  still  the  London  goldsmiths,  became  bankers.  More  than 
once  in  the  next  half  century,  provision  was  made  for  some  public 
oversight  of  the  campsores,  and  in  the  Acts  the  term  bancherius 
and  bancus*  became  frequent  in  what  seems  to  be  a  technical 
sense." 

Early  in  the  fourteenth  century,  therefore,  banks  were  being 
used  to  exchange,  to  remit,  and  to  deposit  money  ;  and  the  bankers 
were  driving  a  thriving  trade  by  investing  the  money  which  thus 
came  into  their  hands.  It  is  clear  that  their  operations  tended 
to  encourage  and  develop  trade.  Not  only  did  they  obviate  the 
risks  of  transport,  or  payment  in  bad  coin,  and  of  the  custody  of 
a  large  amount  of  precious  metals  :  they  also  helped  mercantile 
operations  in  two  other  very  important  ways.  (1)  In  the  con- 
duct of  trade  they  immensely  facilitated  the  adjustment  of  accounts. 


1  A  History  of  Banking  in  all  Nations  iii  217. 

2  Economic  Essays,  145-146. 

3  As  to  the  derivation  of  the  word  see  Oxford  Eng.  Diet,  sub  voc.  Bank.  It  is 
there  pointed  out  that  it  comes  from  banco  or  banco.  =  a  bench  ;  this  term  was 
applied  to  a  tradesman's  counter  or  money-changer's  table;  hence  it  came  to  mean  a 
money  shop  or  bank,  and  in  this  sense  passed  from  Italy  to  other  countries.  In 
Italy  the  word  Monte  was  sometimes  used  in  the  sense  of  bank ;  and  some  have 
thought  that  "bank  "  is  a  German  rendering  of  Monte ;  but  that  is  a  mistake,  as  the 
German  bank  always  =  bench,  and  not  a  mound  or  heap;  the  fact  is  that  "  in  the 
development  of  banking  the  banco  of  the  money-changer  and  monte  or  joint  stock 
capital  were  combined,  and  the  term  '  bank '  applied  in  England  to  both  "  ;  we  find 
"  bank  "  used  in  its  modern  sense  in  England  at  the  end  of  the  fifteenth  and  the 
beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century. 


BANKING  179 

As  the  Venetian  senator  Contarini  said  in  1 584,1  "Buyer  and 
seller  are  satisfied  in  a  moment  while  the  pen  moves  over  the 
page :  whereas  a  day  would  not  be  enough  to  complete  the  con- 
tract for  a  great  mass  of  merchandize  by  counting  a  great  number  of 
coins."  We  have  seen  that  at  the  great  fairs  the  bankers  adjusted 
the  accounts  of  the  chief  trading  centres  of  Europe.*2  In  the 
sixteenth  century  it  was  at  the  fairs  of  Lyons,  the  Spanish  fairs, 
and  the  fairs  of  Genoa,  that  this  system  was  gradually  perfected ; 
and  it  was  this  adjustment  of  accounts  which  was  the  most 
important  function  of  these  fairs.3  (2)  By  lending  the  funds  at 
their  disposal,  the  bankers  could  finance  profitable  undertakings.1 
And  in  time  they  found  that  they  could  use  for  this  purpose  not 
only  the  money  actually  deposited  with  them,  but  also  their 
credit.  A  promise  by  a  banker  of  good  repute  to  pay  on  demand 
was  as  good  as  money  and  was  taken  as  money.  Thus  in  1584 
Contarini  said  that  a  banker  could  accommodate  his  friends, 
without  payment  of  money,  merely  by  writing  a  brief  entry  of 
credit ;  and  that  he  could  "  satisfy  his  own  desires  for  fine 
furniture  or  jewels  by  merely  writing  two  lines  in  his  books."  5 
Thus,  to  use  modern  terms,  the  Italian  banks  had  become  not 
only  banks  of  deposit,  but  also  banks  of  issue. 

A  direct  result  of  this  function  was  the  growth  of  the  political 
importance  of  the  bank.  The  state  soon  found  that  its  business 
was  one  of  the  undertakings  which  a  bank  would  finance  in  return 
for  privileges  which  it  could  give.6  A  loan  to  the  state  and  a 
state  bank,  in  many  different  places  and  at  many  different  times, 
have  been  related  as  cause  and  effect  The  bank,  established  and 
guaranteed  by  the  state,  could  perform  a  function  somewhat 
analogous  to  that  attributed  to  the  Jew  in  mediaeval  England — it 
could,  like  a  sponge,  suck  up  the  money  of  the  subject,  and  be 
induced  to  squeeze  it  into  the  Exchequer  by  the  payment  of 
interest  and  other  privileges.  It  was  soon  seen  that  this  applica- 
tion of  the  institution  of  banking  to  political  uses  was  capable  of 
extension  to  religious  or  charitable  uses.  The  idea  of  forming  a 
fund  to  finance  the  state  gave  rise  to  the  idea  of  forming  a  similar 

1  Cited  by  Dunbar,  Economic  Essays  148.  a  Above  129-130. 

3Huvelin,  Le  Droit  des  Marches  et  des  Foires,  502-574  ;  Professor  Huvelin  tells 
us  that  after  about  the  year  1570  this  business  was  chiefly  done  at  the  fairs  of  Genoa 
— "  Davanzati  nous  apprend  que  dans  ces  foires  il  ne  s'effectuait  pas  de  transactions 
sur  des  marchandises.  II  y  venait  seulement  cinquante  ou  soixante  banquiers,  chacun 
avec  un  petit  carnet,  pour  regulariser  les  affaires  de  change  de  presque  toute 
PEurope." 

*  Dunbar,  Economic  Essays  149,  says  :  "  Trade  with  the  Levant,  the  western 
trade,  corn,  exchange,  the  accommodation  of  friends,  the  purchase  of  land  and  houses 
— these  were  the  typical  classes  of  a  banker's  investments  in  that  age." 

s  Ibid  149-150. 

*  Thus  Ferrara  calculated  that  at  Venice  between  1457  and  1507  the  banks  had 
lent  sums  amounting  to  5,000,000  lire  to  the  state,  ibid  148-149. 


180  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

fund — a  mons  pietalis — to  finance  the  poor,  and  to  deliver  them 
from  the  clutches  of  the  usurer. 

It  is  clear,  therefore,  that  in  Italy  in  the  sixteenth  century 
banks  had  come  to  play  a  very  important  part  in  the  economic 
life  of  the  state.  Their  utility  to  the  state  itself  and  to  all  classes 
of  persons  in  the  state  was  obvious.  But  both  their  importance 
and  their  utility  made  some  measure  of  state  control  necessary, 
both  in  the  interests  of  its  subjects  and  of  the  state  itself.  The 
history  of  banking  at  Venice  shows  that  it  was  very  necessary  to 
legislate  in  the  interests  of  the  bank's  customers.  Thus  it  was 
found  necessary  to  prohibit  the  bankers  from  making  certain  kinds 
of  investment,1  to  appoint  inspectors  of  banks,2  to  prescribe  the 
times  at  which  bankers  must  attend  to  make  payments  to  their 
customers,3  to  make  it  an  offence  to  refuse  to  pay  cash  on  demand.4 
But  these  measures  were  not  very  successful.  In  I  584  it  was  said 
that  of  the  103  banks  which  had  started  business  in  Venice,  96 
had  come  to  a  bad  end.5  The  remedy  was  found  in  creating  a 
State  Bank  of  Venice  in  1587  to  receive  cash  deposits.6  With 
these  deposits  there  was  to  be  no  trading.  They  were  retained  in 
specie  by  the  bank ;  and  the  expenses  of  the  bank  were  met  by  a 
duty  on  imports.  All  merchants  were  practically  compelled  to 
keep  an  account  at  the  bank,  by  the  provision  of  a  law,  passed  in 
1 593,  that  all  bills  of  exchange  drawn  at  or  upon  Venice  must  be 
paid  by  a  transfer  in  bank.7  The  accounts  of  the  bank  were  kept 
in  bank  money,  which  was  20  per  cent,  more  valuable  than  the 
current  coin.8  This  bank  money,  as  Adam  Smith  explained  in 
reference  to  the  similar  bank  of  Amsterdam,  was  always  more 
highly  prized,  because  it  "  represented  money  exactly  according 
to  the  standard  of  the  mint,"  because  it  was  secure  from  fire, 
robbery,  and  other  accidents,  and  because  it  was  easily  transfer- 
able.9    Thus  the  bank  of  Venice  provided  for  the  transmission  of 

1  Dunbar,  Economic  Essays  148.  2  Ibid  152.  3  Ibid  147. 

4  Ibid  150,  151;  for  regulations  at  Genoa  in  the  fifteenth  century  see  Leges 
Genvenses,  Mon.  Hist.  Pat.  xviii,  Cols.  544,  545,  656-658. 

5  Dunbar,  Economic  Essays  146. 

6  A  public  bank  was  set  up  in  1584,  the  immediate  cause  being  the  failure  of  the 
house  of  Pisani  and  Tiepolo  for  500,000  ducats ;  but  the  Act  was  repealed,  and  the 
bank  was  not  revived  till  1587,  ibid  152,  153. 

7  Ibid  153-155  ;  thus,  as  Dunbar  says,  ibid  145,  the  bank  was  founded  to  take 
over,  under  the  guarantee  of  public  authority,  some  of  the  functions  which  for  over 
270  years  had  been  performed  by  the  private  bankers. 

8  Ibid  161-162. 

9  The  classical  account  of  the  working  of  banks  of  this  kind  is  to  be  found  in 
Adam  Smith's  account  of  the  bank  of  Amsterdam,  Wealth  of  Nations,  Bk.  iv,  chap, 
iii.  He  says  :  "  The  bank  received  both  foreign  coin,  and  the  light  and  worn  coin 
of  the  country,  at  its  real  intrinsic  value  in  the  good  standard  money  of  the  country, 
deducting  only  so  much  as  was  necessary  for  defraying  the  expense  of  the  coinage, 
and  the  other  necessary  expense  of  management.  For  the  value  which  remained 
after  this  small  deduction  was  made,  it  gave  a  credit  in  its  books.     This  credit  was 


BANKING  181 

money,  for  the  maintenance  of  a  supply  of  good  money,  and  for  its 
safe  custody.  But  it  did  nothing  else.  It  took  over  certain 
functions  only  of  the  older  private  banks.  The  bank  of  Amsterdam 
was  a  bank  of  a  similar  character,  and  it  was  called  into  existence 
by  similar  causes — the  difficulty  of  regulating  the  private  bankers,1 
and  of  maintaining  a  standard  medium  of  exchange.2  Similar 
banks  were  established  for  similar  reasons  at  Middleburg,  Rotter- 
dam,3 Frankfort,  and  Hamburg.4 

In  the  interests  of  its  subjects,  therefore,  the  state  had  found 
itself  obliged  to  take  over  the  control  of  the  bank.  But  the  state 
itself  was  sometimes  even  more  directly  interested  in  its  proper 
management.  It  might  be  itself  a  debtor  to  the  bank,  which  had 
for  a  consideration  lent  it  money,  or  taken  over  an  existing  debt.5 
Thus  the  bank  of  St.  George  at  Genoa  took  over  the  state  debt, 
and  the  state  as  security  ceded  its  governmental  powers  over  some 
of  its  territory.6  The  bank  thus  developed  from  a  mere  commercial 
association  into  a  political  power,  in  a  manner  which  reminds  us 
of  the  development  of  our  own  East  India  Company.  Similarly, 
a  second  bank  was  established  at  Venice  in  1619,  which  took  over 
the  state's  liabilities  to  its  creditors,  and  was  in  return  authorized 
to  do  banking  business  of  a  kind  similar  to  that  of  the  earlier  bank 
of  Venice,  with  which  it  amalgamated  in  1637." 

Thus,  at  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  most  important 
banks  in  Europe  were  state  or  public  banks.  The  maladministra- 
tion of  the  private  banks,  and  the  greater  security  offered  by  these 
public  banks,  had,  so  Marquardus  tells  us,  almost  driven  the 
private   banks   out   of  the   field.8     The   private  bankers,   whose 

called  bank  money,  which,  as  it  represented  money  exactly  according  to  the  standard 
of  the  mint,  was  always  of  the  same  real  value  and  intrinsically  worth  more  than 
current  money." 

1  A  History  of  Banking  in  all  Nations  iv  193-195,  ic,6-ig8. 

2  There  was  no  national  currency- ;  a  decree  of  the  Earl  of  Leicester,  1586, 
mentions  130  different  kinds  of  silver  coins  and  370  kinds  of  gold  in  circulation  ;  a 
manual  for  changers  issued  on  the  basis  of  that  decree  fixed  the  prices  for  more  than 
500  kinds  of  gold  and  370  kinds  of  silver  coins,  ibid  192  ;  for  the  fidelity  with  which 
the  bnnk  of  Amsterdam  kept  its  deposits  intact,  see  below  188  n.  7. 

3  A  History  of  Banking  in  all  Nations  iv  201. 

4  Marquardus,  De  lure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum  ii  12-14. 

'Above  179;  see  a  History  of  Banking  in  all  Nations  iii  214  for  some  account 
of  the  loans  of  the  Florentine  bankers  to  the  state. 

6  Ibid  154-155.  7  Dunbar,  Economc  Essays  156-158. 

8  Marquardus,  op.  cit.  ii  12,  18-20  ;  he  says  the  private  banks  "  Paulatim  deficere 
coeperunt.  Cui  malo  administratores  eorum  subvenire  laborantes  permiserunt  aliis, 
maxime  fideiussoiibus,  quibus  quodammodo  obstricti  erant,  txsolvere  in  banco 
pecunias,  quas  in  eo  non  deposuerant.  Inde  factum,  ut  ruinam  invenirent,  unde 
celebritatem  sperabant ;  iis,  scilicet,  qui  pecunias  acceperant,  decoquentibus,  et 
nemine  amplius  apud  eos  deponere  volente.  Hinc  frequentissimaj  decoctiones 
bancheriorum  Genuae,  Neapoli,  Messanae,  Florentiae,  etc.,  acciderunt  .  .  .  Unde 
factum,  ut  usus  privatorum  bancorum  fere  in  desuetudinem  abiret  .  .  .  Viget  tamen 
adhuc  publica  banca,  magna  cum  negociatorum  utilitate." 


182  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

business  was  done  at  the  great  fairs,  were  almost  the  only  ones 
who  had  survived.1 

At  this  period  a  bank,  and  the  deposit  business  of  a  bank, 
could  be  described  in  terms  which  a  modern  lawyer  might  use. 
"By  banking,"  says  Marquardus,2  "is  signified  a  certain  kind  of 
dealing  in  money,  approved  by  the  state,  according  to  which 
money  is  deposited  with  bankers  for  the  benefit  of  the  depositor, 
so  that  the  ownership  of  the  money  passes  to  them,  and  so  that 
the  creditors  (i.e.  depositors)  get  security,  and  the  debtors  (i.e.  the 
bankers)  get  advantage.  This  condition  is  however  implied,  that 
the  depositor  may  whenever  he  pleases  demand  the  money  de- 
posited ;  and  this  condition  must  always  be  understood  to  apply 
to  all  such  deposits."  The  mutual  advantage  of  a  bank  to 
customer  and  banker  is  explained  to  consist  in  the  fact  that  the 
depositor  is  relieved  of  the  anxiety  of  seeing  to  the  safe  custody 
of  the  money,  while  the  banker  can  make  a  profit  out  of  the  money 
so  paid  to  him ; 3  and  the  universal  prevalence  of  the  custom 
among  merchants  in  Italy  and  Germany  of  effecting  payments  by 
means  of  entries  in  bankers'  books  is  attested.4 

Malynes  described  the  public  bank  and  its  working  as  he 
knew  it  on  the  Continent ; 5  and  his  account  is  probably  the  first 
literary  statement  in  English  of  a  phenomenon  familiar  enough  in 
mercantile  practice.  He  begins  by  defining  a  bank  in  much  the 
same  way  as  Marquardus — it  is  "a  collection  of  all  the  ready 
money  of  some  kingdom,  commonwealth,  or  province,  as  also  of  a 
particular  city  or  town,  into  the  hands  of  some  persons  licensed 
and  established  thereunto  by  publick  authority."  c     The  bankers 

1  Marquardus,  op.  cit.  ii  12,  ig :  "  Exceptis  iis  quae  ...  in  feriis  ex  necessitate 
retinentur  "  ;  "  competit  autem  hodie  in  feriis  nomen  bancheriorum  illis  mercatoribus, 
qui  non  tantum  suas  pecunias  in  cambiorum  negociationibus  occupatas  habent ;  sed 
qui  etiam,  finitis  feriis  bilanciam  exhibent,  secundum  regulas  et  leges  feriarum." 

2  Ibid  12,  13  :  "  Et  denotatur  per  bancum  certum  negociationis  genus  in  pecuniis 
consistens,  publica  auctoritate  approbatum,  quo  pecuniae  apud  Bancherios  ...  in 
securitatem  Creditorum  et  utilitatem  Debitorum  numeranti  deponuntur  ita  ut 
dominium  ad  hos  transeat  .  .  .  Hac  tamen  tacita  conditione,  ut  quilibet  deponens 
ad  libitum  nummos  depositos  recipere  possit.     Quod  absolute  omni  deposito  inest." 

3  Ibid  12,  16,  17  the  advantages  are:  "ut  deponentes  custodia  et  periculo 
subleventur ;  depositarii,  vero,  qui  pecunias  illas  maximam  partem  non  patiuntur 
esse  vacuas,  ...  ex  usu  earum  quas  vel  in  merces  vel  in  cambia  imponunt,  lucrum 
sentiant." 

4  "  Consuetudo  tamen  et  stylus  mercantilis  in  Italia  et  Germania  viget,  ut  quae- 
libet  promissio,  facta  in  Banco,  cedat  loco  solutionis ;  quod  eo  magis  procedit,  quando 
in  libris  illius,  qui  erat  creditor,  facta  est  mentio  de  tali  promissione  Bancherii, 
referendo  ilium  in  numerum  debitorum,  et  talem  promissionem  scribendo  loco  solu- 
tionis receptae  a  Creditore  et  factae  a  Debitore,"  ibid  ii  14.  3. 

8  Lex  Mercatoria  Bk.  i  chap.  xx. 

6  Cp.  the  definition  of  S.  Lamb,  Seasonable  Observations  humbly  offered  to  his 
Highness  the  Lord  Protector  (1659),  Somers'  Tracts  vi  at  p.  457 — "  A  bank  is  a 
certain  number  of  men  of  estates  and  credit  joined  together  in  a  joint  stock,  being,  as 
it  were,  the  general  cash  keepers  or  treasurers  of  that  place  where  they  are  settled, 
letting  out  imaginary  money  at  interest  at  2  and  J  or  3L  per  cent,  to  tradesmen,  or 


BANKING  183 

have  their  factors  in  all  the  great  trading  centres  of  Europe,  and 
keep  account  with  every  man  whose  money  they  have  received. 
By  means  of  entries  in  the  bankers'  books,  large  sums  of  money 
can  easily  be  paid  and  received.  They  pay  out  money  on  demand, 
and  remit  it  to  foreign  countries  for  their  customers  by  means  of 
bills  of  exchange.  The  money  in  their  hands  is  employed  in 
many  ways — in  "dealing  with  great  princes  and  potentates  that 
have  need  of  money  for  the  maintenance  of  their  wars,"  in  ingros- 
sing  commodities  and  in  fixing  rates  of  exchange  for  different 
places.  These  rates  were  sometimes  excessive,  "  wherefore  the 
city  of  Amsterdam  (to  countermine  them)  have  in  the  year  1608 
also  erected  a  very  great  bank,  for  which  the  said  city  hath 
undertaken  to  answer,  whereby  they  are  always  stored  with 
money,  as  appeareth,  that  the  same  is  plentifully  to  be  had  at 
interest,  at  six  and  seven  in  the  hundred  by  the  year,  and  some  at 
five  and  under."  We  shall  see  that  this  possibility  of  getting 
cheap  money  through  a  bank  guaranteed  by  the  state  was  one 
of  the  reasons  for  the  foundation  of  the  Bank  of  England.1 

It  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  in  England,  from  the  latter  part 
of  the  sixteenth  century,  the  advantages  of  establishing  a  public 
bank,  of  the  kind  familiar  on  the  Continent,  was  pressed  upon  the 
Government.  A  proposal  to  establish  banks  "for  the  relief  of 
common  necessity "  was  introduced  into  an  abortive  bill  on  the 
subject  of  usury  in  1 571.2  In  or  about  1 576  one  Stephan  Parrotte 
proposed  to  establish  a  public  bank;3  and  in  1 581  Christopher 
Hagenbuck  and  his  partners,  who  were  probably  Italians,  had  put 
before  the  Queen  and  Council  a  project  for  the  establishment  of 
such  a  bank.'4  In  1622  Sir  Robert  Heath  made  a  similar  proposal;5 
and  in  16276  we  hear  of  a  suggestion  for  the  "formation  of  a 
national  bank,  or  treasure  permanent  to  be  lent  out  at  5  per  cent, 
to  enable  merchants  to  traffic,  gentlemen  yeomen  and  husbandmen 
to  till  their  grounds,  and  artificers  to  work  and  trade  " — the  capital 
stock  to  be  raised  by  taxation.  In  1636  Philip  Burlamachi 
proposed  the  establishment  of  a  bank  through  which  the  payment 
of  all  large  sums  should  be  made;7  and  in  1641  Sir  Balthasar 
Gerbier   suggested    the    establishment   of    banks    which   should 

others  .  .  .,  and  making  payment  thereof  by  assignation,  and  passing  each  man's 
account  from  one  to  another  with  much  facility  and  ease,  and  saving  much  trouble  in 
receiving  and  paying  of  money,  besides  many  suits  in  law,  and  other  losses  and  incon- 
veniences, which  do  much  hinder  trade." 

1  Below  189.  2  Tawney,  Wilson  on  Usury  125,  159. 

3  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Documents  iii  370-377. 

4S.P.  Dom.  1581-1590,  31,  cl.  73;  the  petition  is  in  Italian;  Bacon,  in  1612, 
mentions  projects  to  establish  a  Bank  of  Exchange  which  should  be  able  to  lend 
money  to  traders,  Letters  and  Life  (Ed.  Spedding)  iv  325. 

SS.P.  Dom.  1619-1623,  386,  cxxx  28-32. 

6  Ibid  1627-1628,  493-494,  lxxxix  17. 

7  Ibid  1636-1637,  73,  cccxxix  34. 


184  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

combine  pawnbroking  with  banking  business.1  In  1 66 1  Sir  Gerbier 
D'Ouvilly  described  the  advantages  of  establishing  a  "Bank  of 
Exchange," 2  which  was  to  have  its  own  "  bank  money, "  and  power 
to  lend  on  real  estate.  In  1 673-1 674  one  Thomas  Newcome  wrote 
a  pamphlet  advocating  the  establishment  of  banks  of  credit,  at 
which  all  payments  by  and  to  the  crown  should  be  made.  Those 
receiving  money  in  this  way  were  to  be  able  to  assign  the  amount 
credited  to  them  by  the  bank ;  and  for  debts  payable  by  the  king, 
bills  of  credit  should  be  issued,  which  the  crown  should  receive  in 
payment  of  debts  due  to  it,  and  should  "pass  under  the  name  of 
check  or  bank  money." 3  The  advantages  of  such  an  undertaking 
were  very  clearly  pointed  out  in  a  paper  written  by  S.  Lamb,  a  mer- 
chant, in  1659,  and  entitled  "  Seasonable  Observations."  4  In  many 
economic  matters  the  Dutch  were  pointed  to  as  an  example  at  this 
period ;  and  Lamb  begins  by  showing  how  much  their  trade  had 
benefited  by  their  public  banks.5  He  then  pointed  out  that  such 
a  bank  in  England  would  increase  trade,  as  it  would  enable  money 
to  be  borrowed  by  industrious  merchants  at  reasonable  rates ;  and 
that  this  would  tend  to  keep  good  men  from  failing.6  It  would 
guard  against  the  risks  of  the  transport  of  money,  and  the  risks  of 
being  paid  in  bad  or  depreciated  money.7  It  would  provide  an 
easy  method  of  paying  debts  by  the  simple  process  of  entry  in  the 
bank's  books.8  He  therefore  proposed  that  such  a  bank  should  be 
established,  and  that  a  society  of  merchants,  to  be  chosen  from  the 
various  companies  of  merchants,  should  be  appointed  to  manage  it.9 
Any  one  who  wished  was  to  be  at  liberty  to  deposit  his  money 
there,  and  to  have  it  again  on  demand.10  The  bank  was  to  have 
the  power  of  issuing  paper  money ;  and  all  bills  of  exchange  were 
to  be  received  and  paid  there.11  The  expenses  of  management 
were  to  be  defrayed  from  the  profits,  and  any  surplus  was  to  go  in 
augmentation  of  the  bank's  capital.  There  was  to  be  a  branch 
to  do  a  pawnbroking  business  on  reasonable  terms.12  In  1676  a 
"  Bank  of  Credit,"  which  should  lend  money  to  merchants,  was 
proposed,  and  actually  founded ;  but  it  failed.13 

'S.P.  Dom.  1640-1641,  527,  cccclxxviii  96. 

2  Ibid  1661-1662,  78,  xl  131;  J.  R.  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  i  274;  and 
for  another  project  in  1665  see  ibid  i  281 ;  cp.  Petly,  Political  Arithmatick,  Economic 
Writings  (Ed.  Hull)  i  265. 

3S.P.  Dom.  1673-1675,  186.  4Somers'  Tracts  vi  446-465. 

5  Ranke,  History  of  England  in  the  Seventeenth  Century  (Eng.  Tr.)  v  77,  says 
that  "the  Dutch  had  been  heard  to  say  that,  so  long  as  England  did  not  set  up  a 
bank  .  .  .  Dutch  commerce  would  keep  ahead  of  English." 

6Somers'  Tracts  vi  456;  see  S.P.  Dom.  1665-1666,  184,  cxliii  114  for  alpamphlet 
describing  the  advantages  of  creating  an  office  of  credit  for  the  benefit  of  traders. 

7  Somers'  Tracts  vi  457.  8  Ibid. 

9  Ibid  459 ;  the  companies  named  are  the  East  India,  Turkey,  Merchant 
Adventurers,  East  Country,  Muscovy,  Greenland,  and  Guinea. 

10  Ibid.  ll  Ibid.  «  Ibid  460. 

13  J.  R.  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  202;  and  see  S.P.  Dom.  1676-1677,  72; 
in  1676  an  office  for  the  discount  of  bills  had  been  started,  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  293 ;  and 


BANKING  185 

But,  though  no  public  bank  was  established,  the  exigencies  of 
trade,  and  the  convenience  of  a  bank  as  a  place  for  the  safe  custody 
of  money,  led  to  the  growth  of  a  system  of  private  banking.  This 
business  was  not  a  definitely  organized  and  a  separate  business  in 
Elizabeth's  reign.1  It  was  not  then  definitely  connected  with  the 
goldsmiths,2  but  rather  with  the  scriveners3  and  the  clothing  and 
woollen  trades.4  But  it  was  eventually  monopolized  by  the  gold- 
smiths. The  nature  of  their  trade  compelled  them  to  deal  in  the 
precious  metals ;  and  early  in  the  seventeenth  century  they  seem 
to  have  begun  the  business  of  exchanging  money.5  An  attempt 
was  made  to  stop  them  from  exercising  the  business  of  exchange  in 
1 627,'  but  it  was  ineffectual.  Without  ceasing  to  exercise  either 
of  these  two  branches  of  their  business,7  they  added  to  it,  possibly 
before  the  middle  of  the  seventeenth  century,8  the  business  of  receiv- 
ing money  for  safe  custody,  and  receiving  the  rents  of  gentlemen's 
estates.9  On  this  money  they  allowed  interest,10  and  made  large 
fortunes  by  lending  it  to  the  government  or  to  private  persons.11 

in  the  same  year  Yaranton  proposed  a  bank  "  in  each  important  trading  centre  based 
on  land  security  and  dependent  on  a  register  of  titles,"  Scott,  op.  cit.  i.  293. 

1  Tawney,  Wilson  on  Usury  88  says,  "  it  is  not  possible  in  the  England  of 
Elizabeth  ...  to  point  to  half  a  dozen  members  of  a  single  craft  as  par  excellence  the 
'  bankers  '  " — rather  the  business  of  money-lending  was  carried  on  by  various  traders 
as  subsidiary  to  their  proper  businesses  ;  as  he  roints  out,  even  in  the  eighteenth  century 
county  bankers  combined  banking  with  other  kinds  of  business,  ibid  91. 

^"The  country  gentleman  who  fifty  years  later  would  have  drawn  on  his 
goldsmith,  when  he  wants  a  loan  of  ,£200  in  the  sixteenth  century  writes  to  his  draper, 
and  that  though  he  is  in  touch  with  a  goldsmith  who  has  already  made  him  advances," 
ibid  94-95,  citing  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  MSS.  of  Lord  Middleton  157. 

3  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  2  subsect.  3  enumerates  among  persons  who  can  be  made 
bankrupt  those  that  "  use  the  trade  or  profession  of  a  scrivener,  receiving  other 
men's  monies  or  estates  into  his  trust  or  custody";  and  this  is  borne  out  by  the 
facts  in  Herbert  v.  Lowns  (1627- 1628)  1  Ch.  Rep.  22;  for  a  good  account  of  this  side 
of  the  scriveners'  trade  see  Tawney,  op.  cit.  96-101. 

4 In  Scotland,  famous  banks  are  connected  with  the  linen  and  corn  trade, 
Cunningham,  History  of  Industry  and  Commerce  ii  455. 

5  In  The  Mystery  of  the  New  Fashioned  Goldsmiths  these  are  treated  as  their 
legitimate  occupations  :  "  In  my  time  their  whole  employment  was  to  make  and  sell 
plate,  to  buy  forreign  Coynes  and  Gold  and  Silver  imported  to  melt  and  cull  them,  and 
cause  some  to  be  coyned  at  the  Mint,  and  with  the  rest  to  furnish  the  Refiners, 
Platemakers,  and  Merchants,  as  they  found  the  price  of  gold  and  silver  to  vary,  and 
as  the  Merchants  had  occasion  for  Forreign  Coynes." 

6  Tudor  and  Stuart  Proclamations  i  no  15 12  ;  for  the  history  of  the  attempt  of  the 
Government  to  control  exchange  business  see  Tawney,  op.  cit.  137-154. 

7Pepys,  Diary  (ed.  Wheatley)  vi  323  (exchanging  money);  v  193 — "Thence 
home,  in  my  way  had  the  opportunity  I  longed  for,  of  seeing  and  saluting  Mrs.  Stokes 
my  little  goldsmith's  wife  in  Paternoster  Row,  and  there  bespoke  some  thing,  a  silver 
chafing  dish  for  warming  plates  "  ;  The  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  124. 

8  The  case  of  Mayor  of  London  v.  Bennet  (1630-1631)  1  Ch.  Rep.  44-45,  in  which 
the  plaintiff  got  an  injunction  against  actions  to  recover  money  from  the  City,  which 
the  City  had  lent  to  James  I.  and  Charles  I.,  points  to  the  existence  of  persons  who 
had  money  deposited  with  them  which  they  were  able  to  lend  at  interest;  cp.  J.  R. 
Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  i  238-239. 

9  Mystery  of  the  New  Fashioned  Goldsmiths;  Pepys,  Diary  v  397 — he  withdrew 
£1000  from  Stokes. 

10  Ibid  253  (March  31,  1666) ;  The  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  132. 
"Evelyn  reports  (June  11,  1696)  that  "  Duncomb,  not  long  since  a  mean  gold- 
smith, having  made  a  purchase  of  the  late  Duke  of  Buckingham's  estate  at  neere 


186  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

This  banking  business  became  well  established  in  the  mercantile 
world  soon  after  the  Restoration ;  and  the  king,  instead  of  dealing 
as  before  with  the  city  of  London  or  with  individual  merchants  for 
a  loan,1  applied  to  these  goldsmiths  or  bankers.2  It  gradually 
became  the  custom  for  private  persons  to  deposit  their  cash  with 
them ;  and  no  doubt  the  way  in  which  the  bankers  met  their 
liabilities,  during  the  run  upon  them  occasioned  by  the  disastrous 
Dutch  war  of  1667,  helped  to  make  the  practice  still  more  usual.3 
Indeed,  it  possessed  such  obvious  advantages  that  not  even  the 
closing  of  the  Exchequer  in  1672  seriously  affected  it.  The  only 
effect  which  it  had  was  to  impress,  both  upon  the  goldsmiths  and 
their  customers,  the  idea  that  the  less  they  had  to  do  with  the 
government  the  better  it  was  for  them.4  "The  public  did  not 
trust  their  money  with  them  unless  they  were  certain  that  they 
had  nothing  to  do  with  the  government."  5 

The  reason  why  no  public  bank  was  established  till  the  last 
years  of  the  seventeenth  century  were  thus  chiefly  political.  A 
public  bank  was  suspected  on  political  grounds  by  the  government 
itself,  by  the  merchants,  and  by  the  public.  It  was  suspected  by 
the  government  because  it  was  thought  with  some  reason  that  it 
might,  by  the  control  of  finance,  get  too  much  power  in  the  state. 
It  was  admitted,  indeed,  that  banks  answered  well  enough  in  a 
republican  state,  like  Holland  or  Venice ;  but  it  was  thought  that 
they  were  wholly  incompatible  with  a  monarchical  form  of  govern- 
ment.6    It  was  suspected  by  the  merchants  and  the  public  because 

^90,000  and  reputed  to  have  neere  as  much  in  cash,"  cited  Grasshopper  in  Lombard 
Street  121. 

1  For  instances  of  this  practice  see  S.P.  Dom.  1639,  276,  ccccxxiii  no.  20;  ibid 
1640,  31-32,  41,  142,  155 ;  Sharpe,  London  and  the  Kingdom  ii  127,  147,  152,  165. 

a  Clarendon,  Continuation  of  Life  (ed.  1843),  1166,  1167;  for  the  king's  depen- 
dence in  the  early  part  of  his  reign  on  Alderman  Backwell,  see  Pepys,  Diary  v  6-7. 

3  Ibid  Sept.  27, 1667  (cited  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  126) :  "  Did  mightily 
wonder  at  the  growth  of  the  credit  of  bankers.  .  .  .  Upon  this  we  had  much 
discourse,  and  I  observed  therein,  to  the  honour  of  this  Citty,  that  I  have  not  heard 
of  one  citizen  of  London  broke  in  all  this  war,  this  plague,  or  this  fire,  and  this 
coming  up  of  the  enemy  among  us." 

4  Before  this  date  the  merchants  were  shy  of  government  business ;  in  1661  Th. 
Clutterbuck,  writing  to  the  Navy  Commissioners,  says  "  he  has  tried  to  negotiate  the 
exchange  business  desired  with  the  English  merchants  there,  but  they  wish  not  to  have 
to  do  with  public  monies,  where  if  punctuality  is  not  observed,  no  constraint  can  be 
used,"  S.P.  Dom.  1661-1662,  46,  xxxix  102 ;  ibid  58,  xl  22. 

s,Ranke,  History  of  England  in  the  Seventeenth  Century  (Eng.  Tr.)  v  77 ;  cp. 
Evelyn's  Diary,  Feb.  12,  1672. 

6 This  argument  was  produced  by  the  Tories  in  1694,  see  Macaulay,  Hist,  of 
Eng.  c.  xx  ;  and  it  was  an  old  one,  see  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  411  n.  2  ;  as 
Cunningham  says,  ibid  412,  "  The  Bank  of  England  proved  itself  to  be  compatible 
with  monarchy,  only  because  the  monarchy  was  now  greatly  limited  by  the  provisions 
of  the  constitution  " ;  even  in  Charles  II. 's  reign,  the  power  which  a  bank  might  gain 
was  beginning  to  be  seen ;  the  Court  was  extravagant,  and  the  amount  of  the  revenue 
fell  seriously  short  of  the  amounts  expected,  and  so,  as  Shaw  says,  Beginnings  of  the 
National  Debt,  401-402,  "  The  city  of  London  and  a  small  coterie  of  London  Bankers 
held  the  government  of  Charles  in  the  hollow  of  their  hands  "  ;  cp.  J.  R.  Scott,  Joint 
Stock  Companies  i  274-275. 


BANKING  187 

it  was  clear  that  any  security  which  the  state  might  give  to  such 
a  bank,  was  far  less  valuable  under  a  monarchical  form  of  govern- 
ment, because  it  was  at  the  mercy  of  the  monarch's  caprice.1 
Charles  J.  in  1640  had  seized  the  merchants'  money  which  had 
been  deposited  in  the  Tower  for  safe  custody  ;2  and  Charles  II.  in 
1672  closed  the  Exchequer,  and  suspended  payment  of  his  debts  to 
the  bankers.3  The  position  was  stated  very  clearly  by  Pepys  in 
a  conversation  which  he  reports  with  Sir  Richard  Ford.4  "The 
unsafe  condition  of  a  bank  under  a  Monarch,  and  the  little  safety 
to  a  Monarch  to  have  any ;  or  Corporation  alone  (as  London  in 
answer  to  Amsterdam)  to  have  so  great  a  wealth  or  credit,  it  is, 
that  which  makes  it  hard  to  have  a  Bank  here.  And  as  to  the 
former,  he  did  tell  us  how  it  sticks  in  the  memory  of  most  merchants 
how  the  late  King  [Charles  L]  (when  by  the  war  between  Holland 
and  France  and  Spayne  all  the  bullion  of  Spayne  was  brought 
hither,  one  third  of  it  to  be  coyned ;  and  indeed  it  was  found 
advantageous  to  the  merchant  to  coyne  most  of  it),  was  persuaded 
in  a  strait  by  my  lord  Cottington  to  seize  upon  the  money  in  the 
Tower,  which,  though  in  a  few  days  the  merchants  concerned  did 
prevail  to  get  it  released,  yet  the  thing  will  never  be  forgot." 

A  public  bank  was  also  opposed  on  economic  grounds.  Some 
merchants,  one  of  whom  was  Malynes,  did  not  wish  to  see  such 
a  bank  established,  because  they  thought  that  it  would  engross 
too  much  of  the  money  of  the  state,  and  that  the  bank  would  use 
it  to  further  its  own  private  interests.5  This  view  was  brought 
out  very  clearly  in  a  tract  of  1676  entitled  "The  Mystery  of  the 
New  Fashioned  Goldsmiths  or  Bankers."6  In  that  tract  the 
goldsmiths  or  bankers  are  accused  of  buying  up  and  sending  good 
money  out  of  the  kingdom,  and  of  lending  money  at  excessive 

1  Lamb,  Seasonable  Observations  (Somers'  Tracts  vi  461-462),  meets  the  objection 
that  "  in  a  monarchical  government  the  supreme  governor  may  seize  or  borrow  the 
money  in  bank,"  by  suggesting  that  a  hw  be  passed  to  make  this  impossible. 

2  See  S.P.  Dom.  1640,  543-544,  cccclxi  104. 

3  For  an  account  of  these  events  see  Macleod,  The  Theory  and  Practice  of  Bank- 
ing i  433-442 ;  as  to  the  meaning  of  Charles  II. *s  closing  of  the  Exchequer  see  W.A. 
Shaw,  The  Beginnings  of  the  National  Debt  391 ;  for  petitions  of  various  creditors  of 
the  goldsmiths,  who  had  been  injured  by  the  suspension  of  payments,  see  Hist.  MSS. 
Com.  9th  Rep.  App.  pt.  ii  121  no.  613  ;  and  for  the  measure  of  relief  given  see  ibid  no. 
628 ;  it  would  seem  that  in  1677  the  interest  promised  by  the  king  to  the  goldsmiths 
was  in  arrear,  S.P.  Dom.  1676-1677,  537. 

4  Diary  v  404-405  (Aug.  17,  1666). 

5  Lex  Mercatoria,  Bk.  iii  c.  ix :  "  Some  men  of  judgment  have  found  my  writing 
to  be  invective  .  .  .  against  bankers,  wherein  they  are  not  mistaken ;  for  the  use  of 
banks  (unless  they  be  countermined  by  other  banks)  are  not  to  be  suffered  in  any  well 
ordered  commonwealth,  as  time  will  manifest  more  and  more.  The  French  king 
Lewis  the  ninth,  and  Phillip  the  Faire  did  with  great  cause  confiscate  the  bankers' 
goods  .  .  .  Phillip  de  Valoys  did  the  like,  and  indicted  them  as  cozeners  of  the 
commonwealth ;  for  it  is  found  that  in  a  short  time,  with  24  thousand  sterling,  they 
had  accumulated  and  gotten  above  two  millions  four  hundred  thousand  pounds.7' 

6  Printed  in  facsimile  by  J.  B.  Martin  in  The  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street 
287-292. 


188  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

rates  of  interest  to  necessitous  persons  and  to  the  government. 
"  These  and  a  hundred  other  practices  they  have  used  and  do  still 
continue,  in  contempt  of  Law  and  Justice,  whereof  they  are  so 
conscious  to  themselves,  that  most  of  them  do  once  a  year  (at 
least)  sue  out  their  general  pardon,  to  avoid  the  penalty  of  those 
wholsom  laws  made  to  prevent  such  frauds,  oppressions,  contempt 
of  government,  and  mischiefs  to  the  publick  as  they  are  dayly 
guilty  of." 

It  was  not  until  after  the  Revolution  that  a  public  bank, 
similar  to  the  public  banks  of  the  Continent,  was  established  in 
this  country.  In  1694  the  Bank  of  England  was  established.1 
It  was  originally,  as  Bagehot  says,  a  "Whig  finance  company."2 
The  Ways  and  Means  Act  of  1694 3  provided  that  the  subscribers 
to  a  loan  of  £1,200,000  to  the  government  should  be  incorpo- 
rated under  the  title  of  the  Governor  and  Company  of  the  Bank 
of  England.4  The  bank  was  to  have  the  power  of  dealing  in 
bullion  and  bills,  of  issuing  assignable  notes,  and  of  lending  on 
merchandise.5  But  it  could  not  trade  with  its  own  securities,  or 
buy  or  sell  goods,  wares,  or  merchandise.6  The  bank,  therefore, 
did  not  follow  the  models  of  the  banks  of  Venice  or  Amsterdam. 
Those  banks,  at  least  in  the  first  centuries  of  their  existence, 
actually  kept  in  specie  all  the  money  deposited  with  them.  Their 
notes  represented  actual  money  in  their  possession.7  The  Bank 
of  England,  on  the  other  hand,  followed  the  system  of  banking 
developed  by  the  goldsmiths.  'It  purported  to  give  in  its  bills 
the  equivalent  of  what  it  had  received,  but  it  never  pretended  to 
take  the  deposit  for  any  other  purpose  than  that  of  trading  with 
it.  It  never  professed  to  make  its  issues  square  exactly  with  its 
coin  and  bullion,  though  of  course  it  made  its  liabilities  square 
with  its  assets,  plus  the  capital  of  its  shareholders,  and  in  time, 
plus  the  reserve  also,  i.e.  its  accumulated  and  undivided  profits. 

1  See  generally  Macaulay,  History  of  England  c.  xx ;  Thorold  Rogers,  The  First 
Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of  England ;  J.  R.  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  199- 
242. 

2  Lombard  Street,  94.  3  5  William  and  Mary  c.  20.  *  §§  19  and  20. 
6§§  28,  29  ;  as  to  these  notes  see  above  174  n.  2 ;  below  190-191. 

6  §  27 ;  the  capital  of  the  bank  was  enlarged  and  further  privileges  were  conferred 
on  it  by  8,  9  William  III.  c.  20. 

7  Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations,  Bk.  iv  c.  iii :  "  The  bank  of  Amsterdam  pro- 
fesses to  lend  out  no  part  of  what  is  deposited  with  it,  but,  for  every  guilder  for  which 
it  gives  credit  in  its  books,  to  keep  in  its  repositories  the  value  of  a  guilder,  either  in 
money  or  bullion.  ...  In  1672,  when  the  French  king  was  at  Utrecht,  the  bank  of 
Amsterdam  paid  so  readily,  as  left  no  doubt  of  the  fidelity  with  which  it  had  observed 
its  engagements.  Some  of  the  pieces  which  were  then  brought  from  its  repositories 
appear  to  have  been  scorched  with  the  fire  which  happened  in  the  town  house  soon 
after  the  bank  was  established  " ;  but,  "  when  Holland  was  overrun  by  the  French  in 
the  early  years  of  the  great  continental  war,  the  whole  of  the  treasure  was  gone.  It 
had  been  lent,  in  defiance  of  the  fundamental  law  of  the  Bank's  constitution,  to  the 
Dutch  East  India  Company,"  Thorold  Rogers,  First  Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of  Eng- 
land 8. 


BANKING  189 

At  first  these  profits  were  derived  from  the  dividends  it  received 
from  Government,  and  from  the  gains  it  made  out  of  the  notes 
which  it  put  into  circulation,  in  exchange  for,  or  in  addition  to, 
the  cash  which  it  took.  It  coined,  in  short,  its  own  credit  into 
paper  money."  ' 

The  services  which  the  bank  did  the  government  in  the  early 
days  of  its  existence  are  matters  of  general  history.  It  financed 
the  Whig  government  handsomely  ; 2  and  the  time  came  when  it 
had  its  reward.  Its  position  as  the  bank  of  the  government  gave 
it  a  wholly  unique  status,  not  only  in  the  nation,  but  also  in  the 
civilized  world.3  Its  services  to  the  commerce  and  industry  of  the 
nation  were  no  less  conspicuous.  Dr.  Cunningham4  has  pointed 
out  that  the  bank  has  conferred  on  the  nation  exactly  those 
benefits  which  Lamb  had  promised  in  1659.5  It  developed  de- 
posit banking.  It  therefore  led  to  the  increase  of  available 
capital,  and  lowered  the  rate  at  which  capital  could  be  borrowed. 
"  From  this  time  onwards  it  became  a  usual  thing  for  careful  men 
to  trade  upon  borrowed  capital,  since  they  found  they  could 
habitually  obtain  the  loan  of  it  on  easy  terms.  During  the  latter 
part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  England  was  hampered  in  every 
way,  both  as  to  internal  development,  and  commerce,  and  coloni- 
zation by  lack  of  capital ;  and  the  banking  system  which  was 
inaugurated  in  1696  had  an  enormous  influence  in  remedying 
these  evils."  6 

During  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  growth 
of  banking  begins  to  be  reflected  in  the  reports  by  one  or  two 
cases,  which  put  a  legal  interpretation  upon  some  parts  of  the 
machinery  by  which  the  bankers  did  their  business.  These  few 
cases,  and  the  statutes  which  established  and  regulated  the  Bank 
of  England,  are  the  beginning  of  the  English  law  of  banks  and 
banking. 

The  reports  show  us  that  the  business  of  banking  will 
eventually  add  a  new  species  to  the  two  classes  of  negotiable 
instruments    then    known    to    mercantile    law.      To  the   bill  of 

1  Thorold  Rogers,  op.  cit.  g. 

2  Ranke,  op.  cit.  v.  80  n.  1,  cites  a  contemporary  pamphlet  which  said  truly  that 
"  the  Bank  of  England  not  only  acts  as  an  ordinary  bank,  but  it  must  be  viewed  as  a 
great  engine  of  State  "  ;  as  he  says,  "  It  was  noticed  directly  how  much  a  very  general 
and  wider  spread  participation  in  the  loans  served  to  strengthen  the  order  of  things 
brought  in  by  the  Revolution";  Macaulay  hardly  exaggerates  when  he  says  that 
"  the  weight  of  the  bank,  which  was  constantly  in  the  scale  of  the  Whigs,  almost 
counterbalanced  the  weight  of  the  Church,  which  was  as  constantly  in  the  scale  of  the 
Tories  "  ;  cp.  J.  R.  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  203-204,  209-210. 

3  Bagehot,  Lombard  Street  97 ;  Ranke,  op.  cit  v.  79,  describes  it  as  an  institu- 
tion "  which  was  destined  to  become  at  length  the  very  heart  of  the  business  of 
London,  of  England,  perhaps  of  the  world." 

4  Op.  cit.  ii  442-446.  6  Above  184. 

6  Cunningham,  op.  cit  ii  446 ;  the  date  1696  is  taken  because  it  was  not  till  after 
the  crisis  of  the  new  coinage  had  been  passed  that  the  Bank  of  England  was  firmly 
established. 


190  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

exchange  will  be  added  the  instrument  by  which  a  person  orders  a 
banker  to  pay — the  cheque  of  modern  law.  To  the  promissory 
note  will  be  added  the  instrument  in  which  the  banker  promises 
to  pay — the  bank  bill  or  bank  note.  With  regard  to  these 
instruments,  three  questions  had  already  risen :  (i)  how  far  were 
they  negotiable ;  (ii)  how  far  would  their  acceptance  operate  to 
discharge  a  debt ;  and  (iii)  what  was  the  obligation  of  the  banker 
who  had  given  such  a  note  to  a  customer  ? 

(i)  There  is  no  doubt  that,  from  the  first,  the  order  given  by 
a  customer  to  the  banker  to  pay  was  regarded  as  a  bill  of  exchange, 
and  therefore  negotiable ; x  and  at  the  present  day  the  Bills  of 
Exchange  Act  defines  the  cheque,  by  which  this  is  now  effected, 
as  "a  bill  of  exchange  drawn  on  a  banker  payable  on  demand.'  2 
Cheques  being  treated  as  bills  of  exchange,  non-payment  by  the 
banker  gave  a  right  of  recourse  against  the  drawer,  unless  he  had 
accepted  it  in  full  discharge  of  the  debt.3  Side  by  side,  therefore 
with  the  bill  of  exchange,  we  get  a  similar  instrument  which  will 
eventually  become  the  modern  cheque.  On  the  other  hand,  the 
bank  bill  or  bank  note,  by  means  of  which  the  depositor  proved, 
his  right  to  the  sum  deposited  with  the  banker,  was  in  substance  a 
promissory  note.  This  deposit  note,  bank  bill,  or  bank  note  was 
originally  given  for  the  whole  sum  deposited,  and  if  any  of  it  was 
paid  off,  the  amount  so  paid  off  was  marked  on  the  original  note.4 
• '  By  an  improvement  on  the  original  system,  the  receipt  for  the 
gross  deposit  might  be  sub-divided ;  it  was  only  one  step  further 
...  to  give,  instead  of  a  single  promise  to  pay  the  entire  sum,  a 
series  of  promises  to  pay  a  number  of  smaller  sums  making  up  the 
total  of  his  customer's  deposit."5     These  notes  given  by  a  banker 

1 A  reproduction  of  the  oldest  known  cheque,  taken  from  The  Times  of  Jan.  5, 
1915,  will  be  found  in  the  L.Q.R.  xxxiv  25.  For  other  early  specimens  see  The 
Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  129 ;  the  following  is  one : 

"  Bolton  4th  March  1684. 

"  At  sight  hereof  pay  unto  Charles  Duncombe  Esq.  or  order  the  sum  of  four 
hundred  pounds,  and  place  it  to  the  accompt  of 

"  Your  assured  friend, 

"  WINCHESTER. 

"To  Captain  Francis  Child,  Near  Temple  Barre." 

2  45,  46  Victoria  c.  61  §  73.  For  the  evolution  of  the  word  "  cheque  "  see 
Oxford  English  Dictionary,  sub  voc.  Cheque;  it  was  originally  applied  to  the  counter- 
foil attached  to  bills  or  other  similar  instruments  to  check  forgery  or  alteration  ;  it  was 
then  applied  to  any  bill  which  had  such  a  counterfoil — they  were  called  cheque  bills 
or  cheque  notes ;  thus  in  1717  the  Court  of  the  Bank  of  England  ordered  all  who  kept 
accounts  at  the  bank  by  drawn  notes  to  use  cheques ;  it  is  not  till  the  late  eighteenth 
century  that  the  word  is  used  in  its  modern  sense.  For  an  early  use  of  the  word, 
which  is  possibly  connected  with  this  original  meaning  of  the  word  cheque,  see 
above  184  and  n.  3. 

8  Above  162-163,  170 ;  cp.  Ward  v.  Evans  (1709)  2  Ld.  Raym.  928 ;  S.C.  1  Eq. 
Cas.  Ab.  376. 

4  The  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  127 ;  see  Cooksey  v.  Boverie  (1693)  2 
Shower,  K.B.  296-297  for  an  illustration  of  this  practice ;  and  compare  the  modern 
letter  Of  credit. 

6  The  Grasshopper  in  Lombard  Street  127. 


BANKING  191 

might  represent  not  only  an  actual  deposit,  but  a  sum  which  the 
banker  had  agreed  to  lend  to  a  borrower.  Because  they  were  in 
substance  promissory  notes,  they  were  treated  by  Holt  as  not 
negotiable ; 1  and  only  became  negotiable  by  the  Act  of  1 704.2 
It  is  true  that  there  is  one  case  in  which  apparently  Holt  treated 
them  as  negotiable ; 3  and,  as  we  have  seen,  we  must  explain  that 
case,  either  by  supposing  that  the  notes  in  that  case  were  drawn 
as  bills,  or  that  they  were  Bank  of  England  notes,  which  were 
considered  to  have  been  made  negotiable  by  the  Act  of  1694. 
However  that  may  be,  there  is  no  doubt  that  their  negotiable 
character  was  finally  fixed  in  1704. 

(ii)  Neither  a  cheque  nor  a  note  operated  as  payment  until  it 
was  honoured,4  unless  it  was  accepted  in  full  discharge  of  the  debt 
That  it  was  so  accepted  was  somewhat  easily  proved ; 5  and  it 
might  be  presumed  if  persons  to  whom  it  was  delivered  delayed  to 
demand  payment.6  But  such  delivery  was  not  in  itself  payment ; 
and  if  a  servant  or  agent  were  directed  to  obtain  payment,  he  was 
not  thereby  authorized  to  take  a  note  of  this  kind."  It  is  only  as 
a  result  of  legislation  8  that  Bank  of  England  notes  are  legal  tender 
(except  as  against  the  bank),  and  therefore  operate  as  absolute 
payment  It  is  true  that,  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth 
century,  the  merchants  said  that  it  was  their  custom  to  treat  the 
receipt  of  these  notes  as  absolute  payment9  But  Holt  decided,  and, 
except  in  so  far  as  it  has  been  modified  by  the  Legislature,  it  is  still 
the  law  that  payment  by  cheque  or  bank  note  is  not  absolute 
payment,10  unless  it  can  be  inferred  that  the  parties  have  agreed  to 
take  it  as  such  payment.11 

1  Above  172.  J  3,  4  Anne  c.  9  ;  above  173. 

8  Above  174  n.  2. 

4 "When  such  a  note  is  given  in  payment,  it  is  always  intended  to  be  taken 
under  this  condition,  to  be  payment  if  the  money  be  paid  thereon  in  convenient  time," 
Ward  v.  Evans  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  950  per  Holt,  C.J. ;  later  it  was  held  that 
if  bank  notes  were  offered  and  no  objection  was  made,  these  would  be  a  good  tender, 
i.e.  the  presumption  was  in  favour  of  payment,  Wright  v.  Reed  (1790)  3  T.R.  554; 
the  fact  that  they  could  be  objected  to  shows  that  they  were  not  regarded  as  cash. 

8  Vernon  v.  Boverie  (1683),  Cooksey  v.  Boverie  (1693)  2  Shower  K.B.  296-297. 

6  Ward  v.  Evans  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  930  per  Holt,  C.J. :  "  If  the  party  who 
takes  the  note  keep  it  by  him  for  several  days  without  demanding  it,  and  the  person 
who  ought  to  pay  it  becomes  insolvent,"  it  would  operate  as  payment 

7  Ward  v.  Evans  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  330. 

8  3  and  4  William  IV.  c.  98  §  6 ;  Wright  v.  Reed  (1790)  3  T.R.  554  per  Buller,  J. 

9  "  The  notes  of  goldsmiths  (whether  they  be  payable  to  order  or  to  bearer)  are 
always  accounted  among  merchants  as  ready  cash,  and  not  as  bills  of  exchange," 
Tassell  and  Lee  v.  Lewis  (1696)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  744. 

10  Ward  v.  Evans  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  330 ;  cp.  Hopkins  v.  Geary  (1702) 
referred  to  in  Tassell  and  Lee  v.  Lewis  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  744 ;  as  Mr.  Street  says, 
the  usage  to  consider  these  notes  as  absolute  payment  "  may  have  been  at  the  point  of 
maturing  into  a  custom,  but  Ward  v.  Evans  settled  the  law  the  other  way,"  Principles 
of  Legal  Liability  ii  391 ;  Holt's  decision  would  seem  to  have  been  in  substantial 
accord  with  the  continental  practice  as  stated  by  Marquardus,  above  182  n.  4 ;  though 
possibly  the  presumption  of  payment  was  stronger  on  the  Continent,  and  therefore 
more  like  the  law  contended  for  by  the  merchants  in  Tassell  and  Lee  v.  Lewis,  see 
last  note.  u  Above  170  n.  2. 


192  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

(iii)  On  the  other  hand,  if  a  banker  gave  a  note  to  his  customer 
promising  to  pay,  the  mere  fact  that  he  had  given  it  in  return  for  a 
note  upon  another  person  which  he  could  not  collect,  did  not  dis- 
charge him.1  It  would  seem  that  in  such  a  case  he  could  not  safely 
give  such  a  note  till  he  had  actually  collected  the  money. 

In  this  period  the  institution  of  banking  is  very  new,  and  the 
law  is  scanty.  We  must  wait  till  the  following  period  for  the 
elucidation  of  the  many  difficult  legal  problems  to  which  it  gave 
rise.  At  this  point  we  must  turn  to  the  history  of  those  com- 
mercial societies,  whose  extensive  transactions  had  rendered  it 
necessary  for  English  Law  to  become  acquainted,  both  with  the 
properties  of  negotiable  instruments  and  with  the  institution  of 
banking. 

§  4.  Commercial  Societies 

The  commercial  societies  known  to  our  modern  law  are  associa- 
tions formed  for  the  purpose  of  making  profits  and  of  sharing  them 
among  their  members  ;  and  these  associations  are,  with  the  excep- 
tion of  those  which  have  a  special  statutory  status,  either  corporate 
companies  or  unincorporate  partnerships.2  At  the  end  of  this 
period  English  law  had  in  substance  reached  this  position.  The 
joint  stock  company  with  freely  transferable  shares,  for  which  there 
was  a  market,  was  a  familiar  object.  A  special  class  of  dealers 
in  these  shares  had  arisen ; 3  and  also  a  special  class  who  made  it 
their  business  to  promote  their  formation.  Both  the  arts  of  these 
promotors,  and  the  modern  phenomena  of  speculation,  were  known 
to  the  world  of  commerce,  and  had  begun  to  attract  the  attention 
of  the  government.4  Side  by  side  with  the  joint  stock  company 
was  the  unincorporate  partnership ;  and,  though  the  distinction 
between  a  corporate  and  an  unincorporate  body  was  clear  enough  in 
legal  theory,  it  was  not  as  yet  very  clearly  understood  by  the  com- 
mercial world.  Commercial  men  did  not  firmly  grasp  the  distinc- 
tion between  a  large  partnership  and  a  chartered  company  till  after 
the  passing  of  the  Bubble  Act  in  1720.5  Probably  this  haziness 
was  due  to  the  fact  that  English  law  had  as  yet  very  few  clear  rules 
as  to  the  powers  of  these  commercial  societies,  corporate  or  unin- 
corporate, and  as  to  the  relations  of  their  members  inter  se  or  to 
third  persons.  These  bodies  had  made  their  appearance  in  the 
world  of  commerce ;  but  the  lawyers  had,  as  yet,  hardly  begun  to 

1  Trowel  v.  Evans  (1710)  1  Eq.  Cas.  Ab.  375. 

2  Lindley,  Company  Law  (5th  ed.)  2  citing  Macintyre  v.  Connell  (1851)  1  Sim. 
N.S.  at  p.  233. 

3  Below  214,  224.  4  Below  211-213. 
6  6  George  I.  c.  18  §§  18-29  !  below  219-221. 


COMMERCIAL  ASSOCIATIONS         193 

settle  their   position  in   the  legal  system  or   to  evolve  rules   to 
regulate  their  activities. 

In  this  section,  therefore,  I  must  discuss  chiefly  the  origins  of 
these  commercial  societies,  corporate  and  unincorporate,  and  the 
form  which  they  had  assumed  at  the  end  of  this  period.  I  shall 
deal  with  this  subject  under  the  following  three  heads  :  firstly,  early 
forms  of  commercial  association ;  secondly,  the  application  of  the 
corporate  idea  to  commercial  societies  ;  and,  thirdly,  the  commercial 
companies  and  partnerships  of  the  seventeenth  century. 

Early  Forms  of  Commercial  Association 

The  two  early  forms  of  commercial  association  which  have 
left  their  traces  upon  the  later  law  are  (i)  the  gild,  and  (2)  the 
mediaeval  contract  of  partnership. 

(1)  Gilds  formed  for  many  varied  purposes — religious  and 
social  as  well  as  commercial — had  existed  from  Anglo-Saxon 
times.1  It  is  in  the  Gild  Merchant,  which  appears  soon  after  the 
Norman  Conquest,2  that  we  get  the  earliest  association  for  strictly 
commercial  purposes  ;  and,  later,  we  see  the  rise  of  the  various 
trade  gilds.3  There  are  many  traces  of  the  influence  of  these  gilds 
upon  the  trading  companies  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries.  Their  governing  bodies  often  consisted  of  a  governor 
and  associates  ;  and  it  is  this  form  of  organization  that  the  com- 
mercial companies  of  the  seventeenth  century  adopted.4  In  order 
to  attain  the  objects  for  which  the  gild  was  formed  it  was  often 
necessary  for  them  to  pass  bye-laws,5  and  to  keep  and  audit 
accounts."  This  power  and  duty  is  often  specifically  mentioned  in 
the  charters  of  the  regulated7  and  early  joint  stock  companies.8 
There  was  a  very  close  fellowship  amongst  the  members  of  these 
gilds.  They  might  be  required  to  share  their  purchases  with  their 
fellows ;  and,  later,  the  gild  would  sometimes  appoint  persons  to 
purchase  goods,  which  were  then  divided  among  the  members.9 
Dr.  Scott  has  pointed  out M  that  "  some  of  the  early  [joint  stock] 
companies,  instead  of  paying  what  would  now  be  called  a  dividend, 

1  Stubbs,  C.H.  i  469-472.  2  Ibid  472,  473  ;  vol.  i  540. 

3Stubbs,  C.H.  iii  611,  612  ;  vol.  i  568. 

4  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  i  7 ;  the  Charter  to  the  Merchants  of  Andalusia 
(1505),  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  2,  3,  provided  for  a  counsellor 
or  counsellors  and  twelve  assistants ;  the  Charter  of  the  Levant  Company  (1601),  ibid 
32,  for  a  governor  and  twelve  assistants. 

5  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  7,  8.  «  Ibid. 

7  Levant  Charter  (1601),  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  34; 
Charter  of  Merchants  Trading  to  France  (1612),  ibid  72 ;  Charter  of  the  African 
Company  (1619),  ibid  102,  103  ;  for  the  difference  between  a  regulated  and  a  joint 
stock  company  see  below  206. 

8  Charter  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1568),  ibid  9,  10  ;  the  New  River  Charter  (1620), 
ibid  113. 

9  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  6.  10  Ibid. 

VOL.  VIII.— 13 


194  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

made  a  division  of  commodities  to  the  members.  This  was  pro- 
posed in  the  case  of  the  Society  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1571);  it 
was  a  common  practice  of  the  East  India  Company  in  the  first 
half  of  the  sixteenth  century  ;  and  it  was  the  rule  of  the  Ayr  and 
Newmills  cloth  manufactories  from  1670  to  171 3.  If  it  be 
supposed  that  the  officials  of  the  gild  collected  the  funds  from  the 
members  before  the  goods  were  delivered  to  them,  the  transaction 
resolves  itself  in  its  essentials  into  a  joint  stock  followed  by  a 
commodity  division."  The  very  closeness  of  this  fellowship  left 
its  mark  both  upon  the  conditions  of  the  membership  and  the 
ceremonial  of  these  gilds.  Membership  came  generally  by  birth 
or  apprenticeship ;  the  members  must  take  an  oath  of  fidelity  ; 
they  were  penalized  if  they  did  not  attend  meetings ;  on  fixed 
occasions  there  were  feasts.1  We  can  see  some  of  these 
characteristic  features  in  the  early  trading  companies  ;  for  instance, 
the  conditions  upon  which  membership  in  the  East  India  Company 
could  be  obtained  were  defined  in  161  5,  and  favour  was  shown  to 
relations  or  dependents  of  members  ; 2  the  purchaser  of  a  share  in 
that  company  was  for  a  long  time  obliged  to  take  an  oath  on  ad- 
mission ; 3  and  there  were  penalties  for  absence  from  meetings  and 
disorderly  conduct.4 

It  is,  of  course,  in  the  earlier  history  of  the  commercial  com- 
panies that  the  influence  of  the  gild  tradition  is  most  clearly  marked  ; 
it  is  more  apparent  in  the  regulated  than  the  joint  stock  companies, 
because  their  objects  were  less  strictly  commercial ;  and  it  affects 
their  organization,  and  their  forms  and  ceremonies,  rather  than  the 
manner  in  which  they  conducted  their  trade.  More  exclusively 
commercial  influences  come  from  the  mediaeval  contract  of  partner- 
ship. 

(2)  Right  down  to  the  seventeenth  century,  the  relations  of 
partners  inter  se  maintained  something  of  the  old  gild  tradition,  in 
the  idea  that  there  was  about  them  a  connotation  of  brotherhood. 

1  Scott,  op.  cit.  13,4. 

2Carr,  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xlix  ;  see  the  African  Charter 
(1619),  ibid  105  ;  the  Charter  of  the  King's  Merchants  of  the  New  Trade  (1616),  ibid 
81,  after  enumerating  the  members,  provides  "  that  they  and  every  one  of  them  their 
and  every  of  their  sons  and  apprentices  .  .  .  shall  be  .  .  .  one  body  corporate." 

8  Evelyn's  Diary,  Sept.  27,  1657  :  "  I  tooke  the  oath  at  the  East  India  House  sub- 
scribing £500  " ;  and  this  was  a  common  provision  in  the  charters  ;  see,  e.g.  the 
charter  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1568),  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  10 ; 
London  Gold  Wiredrawers  (1624),  ibid  133.  Later  charters,  e.g.  the  Mine  Ad- 
venturers of  England  (1704),  ibid  245-247,  only  provide  for  an  oath  to  be  taken  by 
the  officers  of  the  company. 

4  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  4  ;  ii  96  ;  speaking  of  the  organization  of  the  East  India  Com- 
pany, he  says  :  "  Its  characteristics  have  frequently  been  noted,  especially  those  that 
contain  elements  of  old  world  picturesqueness,  such  as  the  march  of  the  beadle  carry- 
ing the  subscription  book  or  to  summon  the  adventurers  to  a  court,  the  '  feasts  '  of  the 
freemen,  the  disciplinary  rules  by  which  they  were  fined  for  absence  from  a  meeting, 
late  appearance,  or  a  neglect  of  the  courtesies  of  debate." 


COMMERCIAL  ASSOCIATIONS         195 

The  association  is  a  "companhia."1  The  members  are  "com- 
panions," and  have  inter  se  the  beneficium  competentice*  Indeed, 
some  primitive  forms  of  non-commercial  partnership  in  early  French 
law,3  and  perhaps  in  early  Roman  law,4  are  hardly  distinguished 
from  gilds.  But  such  forms  of  partnership  died  out.  In  a 
primitive  age  they  were  apt  to  facilitate  disorder  ;  and,  when  the 
state  was  beginning  to  make  its  supremacy  felt,  it  frowned  upon 
them.5  It  is  the  commercial  partnership  that  survived  and  de- 
veloped with  expanding  trade ;  and,  in  the  Middle  Ages,  it  took 
two  chief  forms,  both  of  which  have  left  their  marks  upon  the 
commercial  societies  of  our  modern  law.  The  first  of  these  forms 
was  the  commenda,  the  second  the  societas. 

(i)  The  Commenda. — Of  the  general  features  of  this  contract, 
and  of  the  manner  in  which  it  was  used  to  effect  the  loan  of  money 
at  interest  without  incurring  the  guilt  of  usury,  I  have  already 
spoken.6  We  have  seen  that  the  contract  was  in  substance  an 
arrangement  by  which  a  merchant  who  stayed  at  home — the  com- 
mendator — lent  capital  to  a  partner — the  commendatarius — to 
employ  in  trade.  The  commendatarius  was  entitled  to  his  ex- 
penses and,  generally,  to  one-fourth  the  profit.7  If  the  capital 
was  lost  by  no  fault  of  the  commendatarius  the  commendator  bore 
the  loss.8  The  contract  was  very  common  all  over  Europe  in  the 
Middle  Ages,9  and  it  was  known  in  England.10  The  example  cited 
in  the  note,  which  is  dated  April,  121 1,  will  make  the  position  of 
the  parties  to  it  clear.11     This  example  is  an  illustration  of  the 

1  See  Blancard,  Documents  inedits  sur  le  commerce  de  Marseille  au  moyen  age. 
In  this  collection  of  thirteenth  century  documents  this  word  is  usually  used  in  conjunction 
with  the  word  societas  to  distinguish  it  from  a  commenda,  see  e.g.  i  364,  405,  406  ;  ii 
231,  232,  269.  The  following  is  an  example  from  1248  :  "  Ego  Petrus  Anglicus,  pel- 
lerius,  confiteor  et  recognosco  tibi  Petro  Pellerio  civi  Massiliae,  me  habuisse  et  recepisse 
in  societate  et  ex  causa  societatis  a  te  xv  1,  regalium  coronatorum,  renuncians,  etc., 
quam  companhiam  debeo  tenere  salvam,"  etc.,  ibid  333. 

2  Marquardus,  De  Jure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum  ii.  xi  14,  points  out  that  a 
socius  tolorum  bonorum  always  has  this  beneficium,  "  raticne  societatis  quae  jus  frater- 
nitatis  continet,"  and,  "  etiam  socius  unius  rei  in  id  quod  facere  potest  condemnatur, 
at  non  semper,  sed  turn  demum  si  ratione  illius  rei  in  qua  societas  contracta  est  con- 
veniatur." 

3  See  Brissaud,  Histoire  du  Droit  Frangais  ii  1454-1456,  as  to  the  "communautes 
taisibles  de  roturiers  ou  de  serfs." 

4  Girard,  Droit  Roma!n  (2nd  ed.)  562  n.  3. 

5  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1455,  1456.  8  Above  104. 

7 For  specimens,  see  Blancard,  op.  cit  passim;  sometimes  the  commendatarius 
was  given  a  half  share  of  the  profit ;  see  eg.  ibid  ii  180,  217,  218. 

8  The  clause  "ad  fortunam  Dei  .  .  .  et  ad  tuum  resigum,"  see  below,  n.  n, 
which  was  usually  inserted,  had  this  effect. 

9  Mitchell,  Early  History  of  the  Law  Merchant  128. 

10  Select  Cases  on  the  Law  Merchant  (S.S.)  i  77,  78 — a  case  of  the  year  1300  in  the 
Fair  Court  of  St.  Ives  ;  Thomas,  Calendar  of  early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  104-105 — a 
case  of  the  year  1300 ;  ibid  132 — a  case  of  the  year  1302. 

11  "  In  nomine  Domini,  amen.  Manifestum  sit  omnibus  hominibus  hanc  cartam 
audientibus  quod  ego  Bernardus  de  Gardia  confiteor  et  recognosco  me  habuisse  et 
recepisse  a  te  Stephano  de  Mandolio,  in  commenda,  IIII.  1.  et  xvii.  S.  regalium  corona- 
torum, implicatas  in  xxv.  bisancis  milarensium,  in  quibus  penitus  ex  certa  scientia 


196  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

earliest  form  of  commenda,  which  contemplated  a  trading  venture 
beyond  the  seas.  But  later  it  developed  in  different  directions. 
It  came  to  be  used  "  for  internal  trade,  and,  finally,  even  for  local 
industry."  1  At  first  the  capital  was  always  supplied  by  the  com- 
mendator,  but  later  we  get  cases  in  which  both  the  commendator 
and  the  commendatarius  contributed  capital.2  At  first  the  contract 
contemplated  one  undertaking,  but  later  we  have  contracts  which 
contemplate  a  number  of  undertakings,  or  establish  the  relation 
for  a  definite  or  indefinite  period.3  Finally,  in  Italy,  in  the  fifteenth 
century,  we  find  cases  in  which  there  are  a  number  of  commenda- 
tores  or  commendatarii.  The  former  are  in  substance  capitalists 
who  have  invested  money  in  the  undertaking.  They  are  not 
responsible  for  any  debts  beyond  the  amount  of  the  capital  invested, 
and  they  have  no  share  in  the  management.  The  latter  are  in 
substance  the  directors  of  the  undertaking  ;  and  they  are  personally 
liable  to  pay  all  debts  contracted.4  It  is  this  latest  development 
of  the  commenda  which  is  the  direct  ancestor  of  the  French  society 
en  commandite} 

This  form  of  partnership  did  not  take  root  in  England,  and  has 
only  been  introduced  by  the  Act  of  1907.6  This  peculiarity  of 
English  law  is  due  to  several  causes.  Firstly,  the  conquest  by  the 
courts  of  common  law  and  equity  of  the  field  of  commercial  juris- 
diction 7  made  English  commercial  law  very  insular.  Secondly,  in 
the  trades  controlled  by  the  later  regulated  companies  this  form  of 
commercial  society  was  discouraged,  because  it  afforded  a  means  by 
which  persons  not  free  of  the  company  might  succeed  in  trading 
without  being  free  of  the  company.8  Thirdly,  England's  trade  did 
not  begin  to  develop  rapidly  till  the  latter  part  of  the  sixteenth 
century ;  and  by  that  time  the  joint  stock  company  was  emerging.9 
through  which  the  ideas,  implicit  in  the  later  form  of  commenda — 
the  opportunity  for  an  investment  of  capital  and  a  limited  liability 

renuntio  exceptioni  non  tradite  et  non  numerate  peccunie ;  cum  qua  commanda  ibo> 
Deo  duce,  ad  laborandum  in  hoc  itinere  de  Oharano,  et  deinde  ubique,  causa  negociandi 
ad  fortunam  Dei  et  ad  usum  maris  et  ad  tuum  resigum,  ad  quartam  partem  lucri ;  et 
promitto,  auxiliante  Deo,  reducere  totum  dictum  capitale  et  lucrum  in  hac  terra  in  tuum 
posse  vel  tuorum,  et  verum  inde  tibi  vel  tuis  dicam,  et  exinde  recipio  te  in  Dei  fide  et 
mei.  Actum  fuit  trans  Tabulas  Ugonis  Andree,  anno  dominice  incarnationis  MCCXL, 
IV.  nonas  Aprilis,"  Blancard,  op.  cit.  i  8  no.  5. 

1  Ashley,  Economic  History  i  Pt.  II.  415  ;  see  Blancard,  op.  cit.  i  301-302,  for  an 
instance  in  1248  of  a  commenda  for  internal  trade. 

2  Ashley,  op.  cit.  414,  415  ;  see  the  specimen  cited  by  Mitchell,  op.  cit.  126. 

3  Ibid  127. 

4  Ibid  128  :  "  Contracting  in  their  own  name  the  managers  were  responsible  for 
the  debts  of  the  association,  while  the  commendators  were  freed,  in  Florence,  as  early 
as  1408,  from  all  liability  beyond  the  amount  of  their  quota.  .  .  .  This  type  of  com- 
menda was  in  the  sixteenth  century  regulated  in  Italy  by  several  city  statutes,  and  in 
the  following  century  in  France." 

5  Ibid  129.  "  7  Edward  VII.  c.  24. 

7  Vol.  i  553-558,  568-573  I  vol.  v  139-148,  152-154. 

8  Scott,  op.  cit.  in.  9  Below  208-209. 


COMMERCIAL  ASSOCIATIONS  197 

— could  be  more  readily  carried  out.  Fourthly,  at  the  beginning 
of  the  eighteenth  century  legislative  opinion  was  hostile  to  the 
limitation  of  liability,  which  was  the  essential  feature  of  the  com- 
menda}  But  it  was  through  the  commenda  that  the  idea  of  a 
society  in  which  the  capitalist  could  invest  and  limit  his  liability 
came  into  the  commercial  law  of  Europe  ;  and,  although  it  left  no 
direct  descendant  in  England,  the  influence  of  this  idea  indirectly 
affected  the  form  of  the  commercial  societies  which  in  England  and 
elsewhere  emerged  in  the  seventeenth  century. 

(ii)  The  Societas. — The  commenda  was  originally  a  temporary 
association  of  two  or  more  persons  to  carry  out  a  particular  com- 
mercial transaction  ;  and  the  relations  between  the  parties  to  it 
were  purely  commercial.  The  societas,  on  the  other  hand,  was  a 
more  permanent  association ;  and,  as  we  have  seen,  the  idea  that 
partners  were  in  some  sense  brothers  lived  long  in  the  law.2 
Though  the  latter  idea  tended  to  evaporate,  the  former  did  not. 
It  may,  indeed,  be  sometimes  difficult  to  distinguish  some  of  the 
later  forms  of  commenda  from  a  societas  ;  but  they  were  always 
treated  as  quite  distinct  transactions  ; 3  and  the  distinction  tended 
to  grow  more  marked  by  reason  of  the  consequences  which  the  law 
deduced  from  the  solidarity  and  permanence  of  this  type  of  associa- 
tion. Thus  the  law  gradually  came  to  the  conclusions,  firstly,  that 
each  partner  represented  the  others,  and  could  bind  the  others  by 
his  contracts  made  on  behalf  of  the  firm  ; 4  and,  secondly,  that  each 
partner  was  personally  liable  without  any  limitation  to  all  the 
creditors  of  the  firm.5  The  closeness  of  the  tie  which  united  the 
members  of  the  societas  is  illustrated  by  the  fact  that  it  often  traded 

1  Below  203-205.  -  Above  194-195. 

3  See  Blancard,  op.  cit.  ii  231,  232 — a  document  in  which  the  parties  enter  into  a 
contract  both  of  societas  and  commenda  ;  the  two  bargains  are  kept  quite  distinct ;  ibid 
ii  103-104,  in  which  a  number  of  contracts  of  commenda  are  converted  into  a  societas  ; 
cp.  Mitchell,  op.  cit.  136. 

4  Ibid  132-134 ;    Brissaud,  op.   cit,   ii    1456,  1457 ;   see   Marquardus  ii.  xi    14 : 
"  Ut  autem   ex  contractu  vel  facto  unius   sociorum    teneatur    socius    alter    non 

solum  hoc  est  necessarium,  (1)  quod  unus  ab  altero  negociationi  propositus  sit  tacite 
vel  expresse  .  .  .  sed  etiam  haec  requiritur,  (2)  quod  ille  socius,  qui  contractus  fuerit, 
eum  celebraverit  nomine  hujus  societatis,  cujus  socios  creditores  vel  contrahentes  con- 
veniri  volunt.  .  .  .  Quod  fit  si  negocia  societatis  a  sociis  simul  et  promiscue  pertrac- 
tantur ;  ita  ut  negociatores  modo  cum  uno  modo  cum  altero  eorum  contrahant  .  .  . 
(3)  hoc  fit  si  plures  mercatores  socii  administrationem  negociationis  committunt  uni 
eorum.  .  .  .  (4)  quando  liber  rationum  sub  unius  socii  nomine  concipituret  describitur 
tunc  ille  caeteros  obligat  in  solidum  "  ;  this  passage  shows  that  the  presumption  in 
favour  of  the  power  of  the  partner  was,  when  he  wrote,  strong ;  but  had  not  yet  de- 
finitely become  a  rule  of  law ;  the  stage  at  which  a  special  authority  was  needed  had 
clearly  passed. 

8  Mitchell,  op.  cit,  135  ;  Huvelin,  Des  Marches  et  des  Foires  484-486 ;  the 
personal  liability  was  not  at  first  unlimited  ;  but  it  always  was  unlimited  in  the  fairs  of 
Champagne  ;  and,  "  il  est  plus  que  probable  que  cette  responsabilite,  qui  donnait  une 
garantie  d'ordre  exceptionel  aux  obligations  contracted  dans  les  foires  de  Champagne, 
n'a  pas  6t6  sans  exercer  une  influence  notable  sur  le  formation  ult^rieure  du  droit  des 
societes." 


198  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

under  a  collective  name.1  "  Bartolus  proves  that  in  his  day  the 
formula  Titius  et  socii  was  already  well  established,  and  that  its  use 
entailed  the  joint  and  several  liability  of  all  the  partners,  even  if  they 
were  not  individually  named."  -  Clearly  we  are  on  the  high  road  to 
the  view  that  the  firm  is  a  legal  person  distinct  from  its  members.3 
Scaccia  maintains  this  thesis  ; 4  and  the  law  of  Scotland,  which  has 
been  more  influenced  by  continental  law  than  English  law,5  has 
adopted  it.6  That  English  law  never  came  to  this  conclusion  is 
due  to  somewhat  the  same  causes  as  prevented  it  from  recognizing 
the  soaVte  en  commandite.1  The  corporate  company  was  more 
convenient  than  an  unincorporate  society  of  this  kind.  The 
lawyers,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  their  own  Inns  of  Court  were 
unincorporated  societies,  found  it  difficult  to  recognize  as  a  separate 
person  any  body  which  was  not  incorporated  ;  and,  as  we  shall  see, 
the  history  of  the  commercial  societies  of  the  seventeenth  century,8 
and  the  action  of  the  Legislature  at  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth 
century,9  tended  to  stiffen  and  confirm  this  attitude  of  the  common 
lawyers.  But,  for  all  that,  the  idea  of  a  permanent  commercial 
society,  which  is  almost  a  distinct  legal  person,  has  influenced 
both  the  companies  and  the  partnerships  of  our  later  law.  The 
advantages  of  a  solidarity,  which  draws  a  clear  line  between  the 
firm  and  the  individuals  composing  it,  was  a  powerful  influence 
which  led  merchants  to  wish  for  the  corporate  form.  And,  if  they 
could  not  attain  this  form,  and  merely  associated  as  an  unincorporate 
firm,  the  ideas  that  each  member  of  the  firm  is  the  other's  agent, 
and  that  their  liability  is  unlimited — ideas  which  were  the  conse- 

1  Huvelin,  op.  cit.  251.  2  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1457. 

3  "  Si  la  soci^te"  a  un  nom  a  elle,  c'est  qu'elle  a  une  personality  distincte,  ind£- 
pendante  de  celle  des  associ£s  ;  ou  tout  au  moins,  si  Ton  ne  va  pas  jusque-la  et  que 
l'on  concoive  qu'un  nom  puisse  etre  donne"  a  un  faisceau  d'int^rets,  il  est  difficile  de 
ne  pas  reconnaitre  que  la  tendance  de  la  societe"  a  constituer  une  personne  civile 
s'accuse  dans  ce  fait.  Fr^quemment,  surtout  pour  plaider  les  associ£s  en  nom  collec- 
tive, au  lieu  d'agir  eux-memes,  ont  un  mandataire  investi  du  pouvoir  d'user  de  la 
raison  sociale,"  ibid. 

4  De  Commerciis  et  Cambio  §  i,  quaest.  i  450  :  "  Aliud  est  corpus  unius  societatis, 
et  aliud  est  quilibet  socius  ipsius  societatis ;  unde  si  socii  societatis  cambii  faciant 
bursam  communem,  et  unum  ex  sociis  constituant  qui  praesit  illi  bursas  communi,  et 
hie  praepositus  petat  ab  uno  ex  sociis  quod  debet  conferre  in  bursam  communem,  et 
iste  socius  respondeat  prasposito,  tu  debes  mihi  tantundem,  compenso  tecum  ;  non  est 
audiendus,  quia  quod  debet  societati  non  potest  compensare  cum  eo  quod  debet  habere 
ab  uno  ex  sociis,  cum  societas  non  teneatur  solvere  debitum  alienum  "  ;  cp.  ibid  §  6, 
gloss.  1,  95. 

5  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  13  n.  6.  °  Pollock,  Partnership  (nth  ed.)  24. 

7  Above  196-197  ;  "  it  might  be  supposed  that,  when  there  came  a  time  at  which 
English  capital  began  to  be  used  in  enterprises  of  magnitude,  the  model  of  the  societas 
would  be  adopted  ;  but  before  that  stage  had  been  reached  the  influence  of  the  Italian 
bankers  in  London  had  greatly  declined.  .  .  .  When  a  considerable  capital  began  to 
be  needed  to  develop  English  industries  about  the  middle  of  the  fifteenth  century  .  .  . 
the  corporate  idea  had  developed  in  such  a  manner  as,  temporarily,  to  check  the  ex- 
tension of  partnership,"  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  2. 

8  Below  214-219.  9  Below  219-221. 


CORPORATE  SOCIETIES  199 

quences  deduced  from  the  nature  of  the  Mediaeval  Societas — have 
left  their  mark  on  our  modern  law  of  partnership.1 

Towards  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century  it  was  clear  that, 
for  the  attainment,  either  of  the  objects  of  the  sociitc  en  cotn- 
mandite,  or  of  the  objects  of  the  larger  specimens  of  the  societas, 
the  corporate  form  was  desirable.  With  the  effects  of  the 
application  of  this  legal  conception  to  commercial  societies  in 
England  we  must  now  deal. 

Tfie  Application  of  the  Corporate  Idea  to  Commercial  Societies 
Before  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century  English  law 
had  acquired  some  knowledge  of  the  ideas  involved  in  corporate 
personality  ; 2  and  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries 
considerable  progress  was  made  in  the  development  of  the  law  on 
this  topic.3  The  value  of  the  application  of  this  legal  conception 
to  the  older  unincorporate  bodies  which  regulated  trade  was  soon 
apparent  It  led  to  better  government  and  a  closer  organization  ; 
and  these  advantages  were  especially  needed  in  the  foreign  trades 
in  which  Englishmen  were  beginning  to  claim  a  share./  From 
the  last  years  of  the  fourteenth  century  onwards,  kings  made 
extensive  grants  of  powers  and  privileges  to  companies  of 
merchants  trading  abroad.  "  In  1391,"  says  Mr.  Carr,4  "  Richard 
II.  empowered  the  English  merchants  in  Prussia  to  meet  and 
elect  a  governor,  who  was  to  rule  over  the  traders,  do  speedy 
justice,  settle  disputes,  and  award  compensation.  Reasonable 
ordinances,  pro  meliori  gubernatione,  made  in  proper  form  with 
the  common  assent,  were  confirmed ;  and  all  and  singular  the 
said  merchants  were  bidden  to  be  helpful.  Within  the  following 
twenty  years  Henry  IV.  gave  similar  privileges  to  the  Havre 
Merchants,  and  to  the  merchants  trading  to  the  Netherlands  and 
to  Norway."  And  there  are  similar  grants  made  at  about  the 
same  period  to  the  Merchant  Adventurers  and  the  Eastland 
Company.5     The   privileges   granted   to   the   companies  trading 

xThe  incidents  of  the  modern  contract  of  partnership  were  fashioned  by  equity  during 
the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries  ;  a  few  rules  had  begun  to  be  developed  during 
this  period,  below  217-218,  242-243  ;  but  its  history  belongs,  like  that  of  many  other 
branches  of  equity,  to  the  iollowing  period. 

1  Vol.  iii  482-487.  s  Chap,  vi  §  2. 

*  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.),  xi,  xii ;  they  got  a  further  charter 
in  1404,  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  8,  9. 

5  Carr,  op.  cit.  xxi,  jorii :  "  Time  wrought  little  change  in  the  charters  of  those 
companies  which  regulated  trade.  .  .  .  The  charters  which  Elizabeth  gave  or  con- 
firmed to  the  Merchant  Adventurers  .  .  .  follow  the  usual  pattern.  Her  patent  of 
1564  to  the  Merchant  Adventurers  of  England  (with  which  the  grants  to  local  bodies 
of  merchants  in  Bristol,  Chester,  York,  Newcastle,  Hull,  and  Exeter  may  be  com- 
pared) largely  repeats  and  extends  an  older  grant  of  1505,  which  in  turn  was  developed 
from  one  of  1407.  .  .  .  Similarly,  in  the  case  of  the  regulated  Eastland  Company, 
the  Elizabethan  patent  is  developed  from  an  original  of  1408,  which  provided  for  the 
government  of  the  Baltic  Merchants." 


200  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

abroad  in  the  sixteenth  century  follow  these  precedents.  The 
grant  to  the  Merchants  of  Andalusia  in  1  505  is  similar  to  these 
earlier  grants ;  and,  as  in  the  earlier  grants,  nothing  is  said  about 
giving  corporate  form  to  their  associations  of  merchants.1  But 
that  was  in  substance  what  was  done  ;  and  in  later  grants  to  some 
of  these  old  companies,  and  in  the  grants  to  the  new  companies, 
they  are  expressly  incorporated,  and  the  consequences  of  incorpora- 
tion are  set  out.2  But  the  actual  privileges  given,  and  the  powers 
to  organize  the  trade,  do  not  materially  differ  from  the  older 
grants ;  and  in  some  of  the  clauses  of  these  charters,  and  in  many 
of  the  observances  of  the  companies,  we  see  traces  of  an  old  gild 
to  which  more  precisely  defined  powers  and  a  corporate  form  have 
been  given  by  royal  charter.3  And  as  it  was  with  foreign  trade 
so  it  was  a  little  later  with  domestic  trade.  Some  of  the  older 
gilds  and  companies,  which  exercised  disciplinary  powers  over 
their  particular  trade,  reappear,  in  substance,  if  not  in  name,  as 
corporate  bodies — to  which  the  Crown  or  Parliament  have  given 
large  powers  of  controlling  their  particular  trade.4 

If  we  look  at  the  early  charters  to  trading  companies,  we  shall 
see  that  they  are  either  made  to  the  merchants  trading  to  foreign 
countries,  in  order  that  the  trade  might  be  properly  organized ; 5 
or  they  are  made  to  merchants  who  wished  to  settle  a  new  trade  in 
parts  where  no  English  merchant  had  as  yet  traded  ;  6  or  they 

1  Carr,  op.  cit.  1-3. 

2  See  e.g.  the  Charter  of  the  Levant  Company  (1601),  Select  Charters  of  Trading 
Companies  (S.S.),  32  :  "  that  they  [the  merchants  before  named]  and  every  of  them 
forever  henceforth  be  and  shall  be  one  body  corporate  and  politic  in  deed  and  in  name 
by  the  Governor  and  Company  of  Merchants  of  London  trading  into  the  Levant  seas  ; 
and  them  by  that  name  one  body  corporate  and  politic  in  deed  and  name  really  and 
fully  for  Us  our  heirs  and  successors  We  do  erect  make  ordain  constitute  and  declare 
by  these  presents."  Then  follow  clauses  allowing  them  capacity  to  hold  and  alienate 
lands,  to  plead  and  be  impleaded  in  the  corporate  name,  and  to  have  a  common 
seal. 

3  Above  193-194 ;  cp.  a  clause  in  the  charter  of  the  King's  Merchants  of  the 
New  Trade  (1616),  which  also  appears  in  the  Merchant  Adventurers'  Charter  of  1564 
(Select  Charters  (S.S.)  86),  which  gives  power  to  the  Governor  and  Assistants  to 
admonish  members  of  the  company  to  come  to  the  assemblies  of  the  company,  and  if 
they  do  not  appear,  to  fine  and  imprison  them.  The  charter  of  the  Mines  Royal 
(1568)  (ibid  12,  13)  gives  power  to  correct  and  punish  by  fine  and  imprisonment 
those  who  disobey  the  orders  of  the  society ;  the  same  charter  (ibid  12)  gives  juris- 
diction over  the  "  causes  differences  variances  controversies  and  complaints  "  of  the 
"  ministers  officers  labourers  and  workmen  of  the  said  corporation." 

4  The  privileges  of  some  of  these  older  associations  were  saved  when  a  charter 
was  granted  to  a  new  company.  Thus,  when  the  Royal  Lutestring  Company  was 
given  a  charter  in  1693,  the  privileges  of  the  Weavers'  Corporation  were  saved, 
Select  Charters  (S.S.)  233,  234 ;  for  those  older  associations  and  their  powers  see 
vol.  ii  391,  466-467;  vol.  iv  321-322. 

6  The  need  for  this  organization  was  the  great  argument  of  those  who  desired  a 
regulated  as  opposed  to  a  free  trade,  see  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xxv;  and  cp.  the 
Charter  of  the  Merchants  Trading  to  France  (1612),  ibid  63,  73,  74  ;  Charter  of  the 
King's  Merchants  of  the  New  Trade  (1616),  ibid  93  ;  S.P.  Dom.  (1673-1675)  291. 

6  In  the  first  charter  of  the  Russia  Company,  which  dates  from  1555,  the 
company  was  styled  "The  Merchants  Adventurers  of  England  for  the  discovery  of 


CORPORATE  SOCIETIES  201 

are  made  to  explorers  who  wished  to  colonize  and  settle  and 
establish  a  trade  in  unappropriated  lands  beyond  the  sea.1  All 
these  companies  want  governmental  powers  and  trading  privileges 
which  the  crown  alone  can  give  them.  In  the  first  place,  they 
want  a  power  to  associate,  as  without  some  definite  permission, 
associations  were  looked  upon  with  suspicion  by  the  government.2 
In  the  second  place,  having  got  the  right  to  associate,  they  want 
powers  of  self-government,3  powers  to  impose  taxes  on  their 
members,4  powers  to  decide  their  own  disputes,5  powers  to  take 
adequate  measures  to  defend  themselves  against  pirates  and  other 
enemies.6  They  want  the  privilege  of  a  monopoly  of  trade," 
dispensation  from  particular  laws  as  to  export  and  import,8  and 
other  laws  9  which  might  hinder  their  trade,  remissions  of  customs 
duties.10  All  these  privileges  the  king,  by  virtue  of  his  wide  pre- 
rogatives to  control  foreign  trade,  could  grant  And  he  was 
inclined  to  grant  them,  because  the  control  which  could  be  thus 
exercised  by  the  company  over  its  members,  was  of  great  assist- 
ance to  the  state  in  the  international  complications  which  often 
arose  out  of  the  various  mercantile  activities  of  its  subjects.11 
Thus,  in  the  first  instance,  corporate  form  was  valued  both  by  the 
king  and  by  the  merchants,  not  so  much  because  it  created  an 

lands  territories  and  isles  dominions  and  seignories  unknown  and  not  before  that  late 
adventure  or  enterprise  by  sea  or  navigation  commonly  frequented,"  Scott,  op.  cit. 
"  37>  3^ !  'ts  privileges  were  confirmed  by  an  Act  of  1566  (which  is  not  printed  in 
the  Record  Com.  Ed.  of  the  Statutes),  and  its  style  was  shortened,  ibid  41,  42; 
Select  Charters  (S.S.)  28-30. 

1  Charter  of  the  Newfoundland  Company  (1611),  ibid  51. 

2  Ibid  xv  n.  1 ;  this  right  was  specially  granted  in  the  Charter  of  the  Merchants 
of  Andalusia  (1529),  ibid  2  ;  and  the  necessity  for  the  grant  of  such  a  right  is  alluded 
to  in  the  charter  of  the  Merchants  of  the  New  Trade  (1616),  ibid  79;  Jeffreys,  C.J.'s, 
dictum  in  The  East  India  Company  v.  Sandys  (16S4)  10  S.T.  at  p.  524,  that  "  numbers 
of  people  could  not  meet  to  traffic  or  merchandize  without  being  in  danger  of  being 
punished  as  unlawful  assemblies,"  had  a  good  deal  of  authority  to  support  it. 

3  These  powers,  of  course,  vary  with  the  nature  of  the  company.  They  are  very 
large  in  the  case  of  companies  like  the  Newfoundland  or  African  Company  ;  they  are 
comparatively  small  in  the  case  of  companies  like  the  Mines  Royal ;  and  in  the  later 
charters  to  purely  commercial  companies  they  diminish  still  further. 

4  This  is  usual  in  all  the  early  regulated  companies. 

8  See  e.g.  the  Charter  of  the  King's  Merchants  of  the  New  Trade  (1616),  Select 
Charters  (S.S.)  85. 

"Thus  in  1613  the  Newfoundland  company  got  power  to  fit  out  and  maintain  at 
the  cost  of  the  fishing  fleet  a  ship  of  war,  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  146. 

7 Charters  cited  above,  200  n.  5  ;  Levant  Chatter  (1601),  ibid  36. 

8  Charter  of  the  Society  of  the  New  Art  (1572),  ibid  24 ;  see  ibid  Introd.  xv, 
xvi. 

9  E.g.  the  Charter  of  the  Mineral  and  Battery  Works  (1568),  ibid  19,  exempts 
employes  from  jury  service;  in  the  Charter  of  the  King's  Merchants  of  the  New 
Trade  (1616),  ibid  84,  12  Henry  VII.  c.  6  is  dispensed  with. 

10  E.g.  the  Newfoundland  Charter  (1611),  ibid  57,  58  ;  and  see  ibid  Introd.  xvi 
n.  2. 

u  Thus  in  1613-1614  complaints  of  outrages  committed  on  Frenchmen  by  a 
person  "  employed  for  Virginia,"  and  by  the  captain  of  a  ship  belonging  to  the 
Muscovy  Company  were  preferred  for  information  to  the  Council  of  Virginia  and  to 
the  Muscovy  Company,  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  316-317. 


202  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

artificial  person  distinct  from  its  members,  as  because  it  created 
a  body  endowed  with  these  governmental  powers  and  trading 
privileges.  It  was  from  the  point  of  view  of  trade  organization 
and  the  foreign  policy  of  the  state,  rather  than  from  the  point  of 
the  interests  of  the  persons  composing  the  company — from  the 
point  of  view  of  public  rather  than  commercial  law — that  the 
corporate  form  was  valued. 

In  the  seventeenth  century,  in  consequence  of  the  rise  of  the 
joint  stock  company,  formed  to  conduct  jointly  some  specific 
trade,1  the  commercial  advantages  of  incorporation  began  clearly 
to  appear.  In  the  first  place,  the  corporate  company,  unless 
created  for  a  definite  period  only,2  was  a  perpetual  ibody.  When 
persons  who  had  formerly  worked  together  as  partners  were 
incorporated,  the  incorporation  got  rid  of  "  divers  and  sundry 
great  inconveniences  which  by  the  several  death  of  the  persons 
abovesaid  or  their  assigns  should  else  from  time  to  time  ensue.J^ 
Secondly,  the  fact  that  it  was  a  corporate  body  made  it  easier  to 
take  legal  proceedings  against  third  persons,4  and  possible  to  take 
such  proceedings  against  their  own  members.5  Thirdly,  the 
possession  of  a  common  seal  made  it  easier  to  authenticate  the 
acts  of  the  corporate  body,  and  to  distinguish  them  from  the  acts 
of  the  individual  corporators.6  Moreover,  it  was  possible  to  pro- 
vide that,  unlike  partnership,  the  votes  of  a  majority  of  the 
corporators  should  bind  the  rest.7  Fourthly,  continuity  of 
management  was  more  easily  attained.8  Fifthly,  some  undertak- 
ings, e.g.  the  New  River  Company,  desired  power  to  make  rules 
affecting  the  general  public,  which  they  could  not  otherwise 
have  acquired.9     Sixthly,  it  was  desirable  to  make  it  quite  clear 

1  Below  208-209. 

2  E.g.  the  East  India  Company,  and  the  Bank  of  England ;  as  Mr.  Carr  says 
(Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xix),  "  they  were  cases  where  exclusive  powers  were  conceded 
of  such  an  unusual  or  experimental  nature  as  to  require  periodical  revision." 

3  Charter  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1568),  ibid  5. 

4  This  power  was  always  inserted,  and  sometimes  at  great  length  ;  see  e.g.  the 
Mines  Royal  Charter  (1568),  ibid  6,  7 ;  see  ibid  Introd.  xix,  xx. 

5  "  An  action  between  a  partner  and  the  firm,  or  between  two  firms  having  a 
common  member,  was  impossible  at  common  law,"  Pollock,  Partnership  (nth  ed.) 
24 ;  it  was  partly  for  this  reason  that  the  Court  of  Chancery  assumed  jurisdiction  in 
such  cases,  Spence,  Equitable  Jurisdiction  i  641. 

6  See  above  197,  for  the  question  how  far  the  act  of  one  partner  could  bind 
the  rest. 

7  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xvi  and  n.  5 ;  in  the  charter  of 
the  Society  of  the  New  Art  (1572),  ibid  26,  a  unanimous  decision  is  required,  probably, 
as  Mr.  Carr  says,  under  the  influence  of  partnership ;  in  other  charters  the  principle 
that  the  majority  decides  is  stated — see  e.g.  the  Charter  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1568), 
ibid  14,  Charter  of  King's  Merchants  of  the  New  Trade  (1616),  ibid  83,  Charter  of 
Mine  Adventurers  of  England  (1704),  ibid  247,  though  this  would  seem  to  be  un- 
necessary in  view  of  33  Henry  VIII.  c.  27. 

8  This  was  put  forward  as  one  of  the  reasons  for  incorporating  those  who  under- 
took to  drain  the  Bedford  Level,  Carr,  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xviii  and  n.  2. 

9  Ibid  no — "The  said  work  hath  not  hitherto  yielded  such  profit  as  was  hoped 
for  .  .  .  partly  for  want  of  power  in  them  [the  adventurers]  to  settle  the  carriage  and 
government  thereof  in  such  order  and  form  as  is  fit  and  convenient." 


CORPORATE  SOCIETIES  203 

that  shares  in  a  company,  though  choses  in  action,  were  trans- 
ferable.1 Seventhly,  it  was  desirable  to  draw  a  line  between  the 
corporate  liability  of  a  company,  and  the  personal  liability  of  the 
members  of  a  company,  for  the  corporate  debts.  Eighthly,  it  was 
desirable  to  settle  the  nature  and  extent  of  the  personal  liability 
of  the  members  of  the  company  to  creditors  of  the  company,  and 
to  the  company  itself.  Of  the  nature  of  the  settlement  of  the  law 
upon  these  last  two  points,  which,  after  some  hesitation,  was 
reached  at  the  close  of  the  seventeenth  century,  and  of  the  way  in 
which  it  was  reached,  some  explanation  must  here  be  given. 

As  early  as  the  fifteenth  century  it  was  clear  that  an  individual 
corporator  was  not  personally  liable  for  the  debts  of  the  corpora- 
tion ; 2  and,  after  some  hesitation,3  this  conclusion  was  ultimately 
accepted  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century.4  Indeed, 
one  of  the  advantages  which  petitioners  for  incorporation  frequently 
set  out,  was  the  clear  separation  which  necessarily  followed  be- 
tween the  liability  of  the  corporation  and  that  of  its  members  ; 5 
and  it  is  clear  from  the  statutes  which  established  the  Bank 
of  England,  that,  if  the  individual  corporators  were  to  be  made 
liable  for  the  debts  of  the  corporation,  this  liability  could  only  be 
imposed  by  express  legislative  enactment6     On  the  other  hand, 

1  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xlix ;  the  existence  of  such  shares  is  assumed  in  the 
Charter  of  the  Mines  Royal  (1568),  ibid  10,  11.  Dr.  Scott  points  out  (op.  cit.  i  443) 
that  *'  as  early  as  the  sixteenth  century  shares  were  sold  outside  personal  acquaintances 
and  without  limiting  conditions  "  ;  and  he  points  out  (ibid  ii  416  n.  2)  that  there  is  an 
instance  of  this  in  a  sale  by  the  earl  of  Leicester  of  part  of  his  holding  in  the  Mineral  and 
Battery  Works  ;  and  for  sales  in  the  early  years  of  the  seventeenth  century,  see  ibid  i 
161 ;  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xlvii  n.  i ;  that  the  law  on  this  point  was  still  in  an  uncertain 
condition  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  it  was  sometimes  thought  desirable  to  state 
expressly  that  shares  should  be  transferable,  see  the  Charters  of  the  African  Com- 
pany (1660  and  1662),  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  175,  180  ;  of  the  Royal  Fishery  (1677), 
ibid  200;  of  the  Mine  Adventurers  (1704),  ibid  245,  246;  and  that,  in  corporations 
established  by  statute,  it  was  still  thought  necessary  to  provide  expressly  that  the 
shares  should  be  transferable,  see  e.g.  the  statute  establishing  the  Greenland 
Company,  4  William  and  Mary  c  17  §§  19-21. 

2  Vol.  iii  484. 

3  See  the  authorities  cittd  by  Carr,  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xviii  n.  1 ;  he  yoints  out 
that  "  the  indenture  which  settled  the  sums  and  rents  due  to  the  king  from  the  Starch- 
makers  Company  (Patent  Rolls,  20  Jac.  I.  It.  x)  provided  that  no  such  sums  'shall 
in  any  sort  be  demanded  levied  recovered  or  had  but  only  of  the  body  corporate '  " ; 
and  that  in  1655  the  governor  of  the  East  India  Company  got  an  indemnity  from 
the  company  *•  because  his  name  is  used  in  all  suits  and  actions " ;  Hobbes 
(Leviathan  120)  thought  that  "  if  a  body  politique  of  merchants  contract  a  debt  to  a 
stranger  by  the  act  of  their  representative  assembly,  every  member  is  lyable  by 
himself  for  the  whole." 

4  Edmunds  v.  Brown  and  Tillard  (1668)  1  Lev.  237;  Salmon  v.  The  Ham- 
borough  Company  ( 1671)  1  Ch.  Cas.  204. 

5  Carr,  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xvii,  xviii,  says  that  the  following  formula,  taken  from 
a  petition  for  incorporation  in  1692,  is  common :  "  The  same  [i.e.  a  joint  stock]  is  not 
to  be  raised  unless  upon  the  establishment  of  a  corporation,  because  if  such  an  under- 
taking should  be  carried  on  only  by  articles  of  partnership,  the  stock  will  be  liable  to 
the  particular  and  private  debts  of  the  several  partners  and  subject  to  be  torn  to  pieces 
upon  the  bankruptcy  of  any  of  them  "  ;  cp.  S.F.  Dom.  (1691-1692)  523-524. 

•  5  and  6  William  and  Mary  c.  20  §  25 — if  the  corporation  borrows  more  than 
£1.200 ,000  the  individual  corporators  are  to  be  personally  liable  ;  8  and  9  William  III. 


204  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  corporators  or  shareholders  were  liable  to  pay  to  the  corpora- 
tion the  sums  assessed  upon  them  by  the  corporation ;  and  the 
power  to  make  these  "leviations"  naturally  took  a  prominent 
place  in  the  charters  of  some  of  these  companies.1  But,  that 
being  so,  it  is  clear  that,  if  creditors  could  get  an  order  from  a 
court  that  the  company  should  make  "leviations"  upon  their 
members,  the  creditors  could  indirectly  make  the  individual 
members  of  the  company  liable  to  the  extent  necessary  to  satisfy 
their  debt.  By  a  sort  of  subrogation  the  creditors  could  use  the 
powers  of  the  company  against  the  individuals  composing  it,  and 
so  force  these  individuals  to  pay.  We  see  this  idea  foreshadowed 
in  a  petition  to  the  council  in  1639;2  in  1653  it  was  proposed  to 
give  it  statutory  force ; 3  and  in  1 67 1  the  principle  was  sanctioned 
by  the  House  of  Lords  in  the  case  of  Salmon  v.  The  Hamborough 
Company}  But  it  should  be  observed  that,  as  the  creditors' 
rights  against  the  individuals  depended  upon  the  existence  of  the 
company's  right  to  make  "  leviations "  upon  the  individuals 
composing  it,  they  lost  these  rights  if  in  fact  the  company  had  no 
power  to  make  leviations.  This  opened  the  door  to  the  possibility 
of  limiting  the  liability  of  members  of  the  company  by  a  contract 
between  the  members  of  the  company  and  the  company,  which 
provided  that  the  members  should  not  be  liable  to  be  called  upon 


c.  20  §  4g — if  the  capital  is  diminished  by  the  payment  of  dividends  so  that  it  is  not 
enough  to  pay  the  corporate  debts  the  members  are  to  be  liable  to  the  extent  of  the 
dividends  received  ;  see  also  6  George  IV.  c.  9  §  2 ;  7  Will.  IV.  and  1  Vict.  c.  73  §  4. 

1  Select  Charters  (S.S.)  xviii  n.  i ;  i,  2,  91,  92,  164,  215  ;  for  instances  in  which 
these  leviations  were  made,  see  Scott,  op.  cit.  ii  47,  48,  59,  66,  80,  366,  367 ;  for 
cases  in  which  the  authority  of  the  council  was  invoked  to  force  payment  of  these 
leviations,  see  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  4th  Rep.  App.  18,  20  (the  Muscovy  Company);  S.P. 
Dom.  (1634)  352,  cclxxviii  39 — Order  of  Council  on  petition  of  the  Governor  and 
Company  of  Silkmen  of  London  ;  ibid  (1637-1638)  260,  ccclxxxii  20 — Order  of  Council 
on  petition  of  the  governor  of  one  of  the  Associations  of  Royal  Fishings ;  cp.  ibid 
(1639)  381,  ccccxxv  43. 

aS.P.  Dom.  (1639)  381,  3S2,  ccccxxv  43. 

3  See  the  Draft  Act  "  for  the  recovery  of  debts  owing  by  corporations,"  Somers' 
Tracts  vi  187 ;  under  that  Act,  if  the  leviations  were  not  made,  execution  was  to  be 
had  against  the  estate  of  the  person  who  ought  to  have  made  it. 

4(i67i)  1  Ch.  Cas.  at  pp.  206,  207,  the  Lords  ordered  that  the  governor  and 
assistants  of  the  company  should  "  make  such  a  leviation  upon  every  member  of  the 
said  company  ...  as  shall  be  sufficient  to  satisfy  the  said  sum  to  be  decreed  to  the 
plaintiff  in  that  cause,  and  to  collect  and  levy  the  same,  and  to  pay  it  over  to  the 
plaintiff  as  the  Court  shall  direct.  .  .  .  And  if  .  .  .  the  said  money  so  to  be  assessed 
shall  not  be  paid,  then  and  from  thenceforth  every  person  of  the  said  company,  upon 
such  a  leviation,  shall  be  made  to  be  liable  in  his  capacity  to  pay  his  quota  or  propor- 
tion assessed.  And  the  Lord  Chancellor  ...  is  to  order  .  .  .  that  such  process  shall 
issue  against  any  such  member  so  refusing  or  delaying  to  pay  his  quota  or  proportion 
as  is  usual  against  persons  charged  by  the  decree  of  the  said  Court,  for  any  duty  in 
their  several  capacities  "  ;  for  further  information  about  this  case  and  the  difficulties 
of  the  company  see  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  8th  Rep.  App.  p.  147  no.  310;  9th  Rep.  App. 
Pt.  ii  p.  27  no.  109;  ibid  p.  47  no.  186;  in  1672-1673  there  is  a  petition  to  the  Home 
of  Lords  by  certain  creditors  of  the  Grocers  Company  that  the  company  should  be 
ordered  to  assess  their  members  to  raise  money  to  pay  them,  ibid  p.  22  no.  87  (/). 


CORPORATE  SOCIETIES  205 

to  pay  more  than  a  fixed  sum.  Such  bargains  were  made ; *  and 
that  they  were  both  common  and  efficacious  may  be  gathered 
from  the  section  of  the  statute  of  1 694,  dealing  with  the  liability 
of  the  shareholders  in  the  Bank  of  England,  which  declared  that, 
in  certain  events,  they  were  to  be  personally  liable  for  certain 
debts,  notwithstanding  any  agreement  which  they  might  have 
made  with  the  company.2  Thus  it  would  seem  that,  by  the 
adoption  of  the  corporate  form,  a  clear  line  could  be  drawn 
between  corporate  liability  and  individual  liability ;  and  that,  by 
bargains  made  between  the  company  and  its  members,  the 
individual  liability  of  the  members  of  the  company  could  be 
limited  in  any  way  agreed  on  between  the  contracting  parties. 

Such,  then,  were  the  commercial  advantages  which  a  society 
might  get  by  assuming  a  corporate  form  ;  and  it  followed  that,  if 
they  were  secured,  the  promoters  were  able  to  secure  the  supreme 
advantage  of  attracting  capital  more  easily  to  finance  their  under- 
taking. In  fact,  a  society  possessing  these  privileges  had  all  and 
more  than  all  the  advantages  both  of  the  societas  and  of  the 
commenda.  It  was  a  permanent  body  quite  distinct  from  its 
members.  Privileges  necessary  for  the  particular  trade  which  it 
proposed  to  carry  on  could  be  secured  It  could  get  powers  to 
coerce  recalcitrant  members,  to  settle  disputes  as  to  the  working  of 
the  company,  and  to  make  necessary  bye-laws.  The  corporate 
liability  of  the  company  and  the  individual  liability  of  its  members 
could  be  adjusted  The  investor  could  be  attracted  by  the  ad- 
vantages of  transferable  shares  and  a  limited  liability. 

The  older  regulated  companies,  formed  to  organize  foreign 
trade,  naturally  preserved  many  of  the  characteristics  of  the 
mediaeval  gilds,  of  which  they  were  the  lineal  descendants.  The 
new  commercial  companies  of  the  joint  stock  type  did  not,  as  we 
have  seen,3  at  once  lose  all  trace  of  these  characteristics.  But 
they  were  more  essentially  commercial ;  and  the  privileges  which 
they  obtained  were  chiefly  reminiscent  of  the  ideas  which  the 
development  of  the  societas  and  the  commenda  had  introduced 
into  continental  law.  We  must  now  trace  the  history  of  the  form 
which  these  ideas  took  in  England  during  the  seventeenth  century. 

1  Scott,  op.  cit,  i  228 — an  agreement  in  163 7- 1638,  that  a  shareholder  in  the 
Mosquito  Islands  Company,  who  had  paid  calls  up  to  £1000,  might  elect  not  to  go 
farther;  ibid  344 — the  shareholders  in  the  Million  Bank  were  promised  that  they 
should  only  be  liable  to  the  extent  of  their  stock.  I  do  not  agree  with  Dr.  Scott  (op. 
cit.  i  270)  that  the  Act  of  14  Charles  II.  c.  24,  which  exempted  certain  shareholders 
from  the  bankruptcy  laws,  amounted  to  a  limitation  of  liability ;  it  only  comes  to  this, 
that  they  were  not  to  be  accounted  traders,  and  so  could  not  be  made  bankrupt ;  if 
they  were  solvent  their  liability  would  be  unlimited. 

*  5  and  6  William  and  Mary  c.  20  §  25. 

*  Above  194. 


206  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

The  Commercial  Companies  and  Partnerships  of  the  Seventeenth 

Century 

I  shall  deal  with  this  topic  under  the  following  heads  : — firstly, 
the  rise  of  the  joint  stock  company  ;  secondly,  its  commercial  and 
legal  consequences ;  thirdly,  the  Bubble  Act  and  its  effect  on  the 
development  of  company  and  partnership  law. 

(i)  The  rise  of  the  joint  stock  company. 

The  main  difference  between  a  regulated  and  a  joint  stock 
company  was  that  in  a  regulated  company  each  member  conducted 
his  own  trade  with  his  own  stock,  subject  to  the  rules  and  regula- 
tions of  the  company,  while  in  a  joint  stock  company  the  company 
traded  as  a  single  person  with  a  stock  contributed  by  its  members.1 
The  first  form  of  association  was  the  older,  and  it  was  well  adapted 
to  a  company  formed  primarily  to  see  that  the  trade  with  which  it 
was  concerned  was  conducted  in  accordance  with  the  commercial 
policy  of  the  state.  The  second  form  of  association  emerged  in 
England  somewhat  later,  and  was  more  adapted  to  a  company 
formed  for  the  strictly  commercial  object  of  making  money  for  its 
members.  It  was  not,  however,  till  the  latter  part  of  the  seven- 
teenth century  that  the  two  forms  of  company  became  clearly 
distinct.  Thus  in  the  East  India  Company  there  was  at  first  a 
system  of  terminable  stocks.2  The  investor  subscribed  only  for  a 
particular  voyage,  and  the  accounts  of  the  different  voyages  were 
kept  separately.3  Each  member  was  free  to  invest  or  not  as  he 
pleased  in  any  given  venture.  What  was  permanent  and  constant 
was  not  the  stock,  but  the  governmental  machinery  of  the  company — 
in  fact,  it  was  not  till  1657  that  a  permanent  joint  stock  was  formed.4 
Clearly  this  arrangement,  though  due  partly  to  the  exceptional 
position  of  this  company,  represents  an  intermediate  stage  between 
a  regulated  company  formed  primarily  for  the  government  of  the 
trade  with  which  it  is  concerned,  and  a  joint  stock  company  formed 
primarily  to  make  a  profit  for  its  members.5  Similarly,  in  some 
of  the  early  English  and  Scotch  joint  stock  companies  there  was  a 
dividend  paid,  not  in  money,  but  in  commodities.6  The  company, 
by  trading  with  its  joint  stock,  acquired  these  commodites,  which 
it  distributed  to  its  members,  and  the  members  were  free  to  dispose 
of  them  as  they  saw  fit.  This  was  the  plan  adopted  by  the  Scotch 
New  Mills  Company,  founded  to  manufacture  cloth  in  1681. 
Membership  of  the  company  was  limited  to  trading  merchants. 
When  the  cloth  was  produced,  the  price  was  fixed  by  reckoning 
the  cost  of  production,  together  with  a  sum  to  represent  interest 

1  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xxi. 

2  Scott,  op.  cit.  ii  96,  97.  3  Ibid  123-128.  4  Ibid  128  et  seq. 
sIbid  96,  97.                                        8  Ibid  i  12,  301,  302. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     207 

on  the  company's  capital.  It  was  then  distributed  lo  members  at 
this  price,  and  they  retailed  it.  Thus,  as  Dr.  Scott  says,  "  it  was 
a  body  in  which  the  members  were  a  regulated  company  as  retailers, 
and  a  joint  stock  one'as  manufacturers."1 

It  will  thus  be  seen  that  the  company  with  a  permanent  joint 
stock,  which  paid  pecuniary  dividends  from  its  earnings  to  its 
members,  only  gradually  differentiated  itself  from  the  regulated 
company.  It  is  not  surprising,  therefore,  to  find  that,  "so  far  as 
the  charters  of  incorporation  are  concerned,  the  change  from  the 
regulated  to  the  joint  stock  type  is  hardly  perceptible."2  By  the 
end  of  this  period,  however,  the  distinction  between  the  two  types 
of  company  was  well  established.  The  question  thus  arises,  What 
was  the  origin  of  the  joint  stock  form  of  commercial  association, 
and  what  were  the  causes  of  its  development? 

There  can  be  little  doubt  that  the  origin  of  the  joint  stock 
principle,  like  the  origin  of  so  many  other  principles  of  our  modern 
commercial  law,  must  be  sought  in  mediaeval  Italy.  Two  elements 
went  to  its  formation — firstly,  ideas  implicit  in  the  societas  ; 3  and, 
secondly,  the  development  of  those  ideas  under  the  pressure  of  the 
use  made  of  them  by  the  state  for  its  own  purposes.  It  is  probable 
that  the  partners  in  a  societas  generally  traded  with  what  was  in 
effect  a  joint  stock.  From  early  times  partnerships  owned  shares 
in  a  ship.  The  shares  were  transferable,  and  liability  upon  them 
was  limited  to  the  value  of  the  ship.4  It  is  clear  that  large 
mercantile  and  banking  partnerships,  such  as  the  Peruzzi  and  the 
Bardi  at  Florence,  must  have  carried  on  their  trade  with  a  capital 
jointly  contributed  by  the  partners.5  We  have  seen  that  this 
feature  of  these  partnerships  tended  to  make  the  partnership  almost 
a  distinct  legal  person,  and  to  make  the  lawyers  regard  it  as  an 
entity  not  very  different  from  a  corporation.6  But  it  was  the  use 
made  of  these  partnerships,  under  the  pressure  of  state  needs,  which 
necessitated  the  development  of  some  of  them  into  corporations  of 
the  joint  stock  type.  States  as  well  as  kings  found  it  necessary 
to  borrow  in  the  Middle  Ages ;  and  just  as  some  of  our  English 
kings  borrowed  from  the  Italian  mercantile  and  banking  societies,7 
so  the  Italian  cities  borrowed  from  their  citizens.  "The  loans 
were  divided  into  shares  {luoghi),  and  the  names  of  the  owners 
were  registered  in  special  books.  The  shares  not  only  passed  to 
the  heirs  in  case  of  the  owner's  death,  but  could  be  freely  bought 

1  Op.  cit.  i  301,  302. 

2  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xxi.  3  Above  197-199. 

4  Thaller,  Les  Soctetes  par  actions  dans  l'ancienne  France,  14,  15. 

5  For  the  names  of  some  of  these  societies,  see  Huvelin,  Marches  et  Foires  251, 
252. 

6  Above  198.  7  Above  177-178. 


208  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and  sold." x  But  to  attract  the  borrower  the  state  found  itself 
obliged  to  give  some  form  of  security  for  the  capital  and  interest. 
Thus,  in  1 346,  Genoa  raised  a  loan  for  the  conquest  of  Chios  and 
Phocea,  and  gave  the  shareholders  the  dominium  utile  of  the  lands 
conquered.2  It  is  obvious  that  the  shareholders  were  in  effect  a 
large  partnership  interested  in  the  exploitation  of  these  lands  ;  and 
it  was  inevitable  that  they  should  assume  a  corporate  form.  Thus 
arose  a  joint  stock  company,  consisting  of  creditors  of  the  state, 
interested  in  exploiting  a  conquered  colony.  But  when  the  in- 
stitution of  banking  became  general,  it  was  also  inevitable  that  it 
should  play  a  great  part  in  developing  this  institution.  It  was,  as 
we  have  seen,3  soon  perceived  that  a  banking  company  could  finance 
both  the  state  and  many  other  undertakings.  Thus,  in  mediaeval 
Italy,  as  in  England  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  banks 
were  formed  which,  in  return  for  financial  aid  to  the  state,  were 
given  privileges  which  they  exploited  as  a  joint  stock  company. 
In  1407  the  bank  of  Genoa  took  over  the  various  state  loans. 
"As  security  for  the  interest  the  city  granted  important  privileges 
to  the  holders  of  the  new  consolidated  stock,  which  was  divided 
into  shares  of  1 00  lires.  The  stockholders  were  granted  the 
right  (1408)  to  carry  on  banking  business,  and  especially  after 
1453  the  administration  and  exploitation  of  important  Genoan 
colonies  passed  into  their  hands.  The  creditors  of  the  Genoan 
state  had  become  the  shareholders  of  a  great  colonial  company 
which  ultimately  governed  and  administered  Corsica,  Kaffa,  and 
the  greater  part  of  the  foreign  dominions  of  Genoa."4 

In  England,  in  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  we 
find  that  the  same  two  elements — the  ideas  implicit  in  the  societas, 
and  the  development  of  those  ideas  under  the  pressure  of  the  use 
made  of  them  by  the  state  for  its  own  purposes — contributed  to 
the  reception  of  the  idea  of  the  joint  stock  company.  The  sequence 
of  events,  and  the  historical  incidents  which  led  to  their  recognition 
and  development,  are,  of  course,  different.  But  we  can  see  that 
substantially  the  same  causes  were  at  work  in  England  at  this 
period  as  those  which  had  been  at  work  in  Italy  in  the  Middle 
Ages. 

In  the  first  place,  bodies  which  started  as  a  large  partnership 
found  it  expedient  to  get  corporate  form,  and  to  carry  on  their 
business  as  a  joint  stock  company.  Thus,  the  Society  of  the 
Mines  Royal,  which  was  founded  in  1 561,5  was  incorporated  in 
1  568  ; 6  and  the  Society  of  the  Mineral  and  Battery  Works,  which 
was  founded  in  1 565/ was  also  incorporated  in  1568.8     Similarly, 

1  Mitchell,  The  Law  Merchant,  138.  2  Ibid.  3  Above  179-180. 

4  Mitchell,  op.  cit.  139.  5  Scott,  op.  cit.  ii  384.  6  Ibid  386. 

7  Ibid  414.  8  Ibid  415. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     209 

the  trade  with  Africa  in  the  sixteenth  century  was  carried  on  by 
various  partnerships  or  syndicates,  to  which  privileges  of  exclusive 
trade  was  granted.1  It  was  not  till  1588  that  the  various  syndicates 
trading  to  Africa  were  incorporated.2  In  the  second  place,  state 
needs  helped  to  foster  the  growth  of  such  companies.  In  England 
the  earliest  of  these  needs  was  not,  as  in  Italy,  the  need  to 
persuade  its  citizens  to  lend  their  money  to  the  state,  but  the 
need  to  organize  foreign  trade  and  to  found  colonies.  In  1553 
the  Russia  Company  was  founded  as  a  joint  stock  company.3  It 
was  followed  in  1581  by  the  Levant  Company;4  in  1600  by  the 
East  India  Company  ; 5  in  1670  by  the  Hudson's  Bay  Company ; 6 
and  in  1672  by  the  Royal  African  Company.7  All  these 
companies  were  founded  primarily  to  develop  foreign  trade.  Of 
the  companies  founded  primarily  to  colonize  we  get,  among  others 
the  Virginia  Company,  founded  in  1609 ; 8  the  Somers  Islands  or 
the  Bermuda  Company,  founded  in  1612  ; 9  and  the  New  England 
Company,  founded  in  1620.10  It  was  not  until  the  end  ot  the 
seventeenth  century  that  the  joint  stock  principle  was  applied  to 
the  financing  of  the  government.  We  have  seen  that  the  Stuart 
kings  had  privately  borrowed  from  the  bankers ;  but  that  it  was 
not  until  the  foundation  of  the  Bank  of  England  that  the  plan 
of  founding  a  bank  as  a  joint  stock  company,  and  of  giving  it 
privileges  in  return  for  a  loan  to  the  government,  was  adopted  in 
England.11 

A  large  number  of  the  joint  stock  companies,  which  were 
founded  in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries,  dis- 
appeared when  changed  conditions  of  trade  and  changed  political 
conditions  made  the  joint  stock  organization  no  longer  suitable. 
During  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century  there  was  a 
movement  in  favour  of  greater  freedom  of  trade.  Monopolistic 
joint  stock  companies  were  successfully  attacked.  In  1605  the 
Levant  Company  had  adopted  the  regulated  form  which  allowed 
greater  freedom  of  trade  to  individuals.12  The  Russia  Company 
made  a  similar  change  in  1669  ; 13  and  the  fine  for  admission  to  the 
company  was  lowered  to  £$  by  a  statute  of  1698.14  Freedom  of 
trade  to  Africa  had  been  practically  conceded  by  another  statute 
of  the  previous  year,  which  threw  the  trade  open,  subject  to  a 
payment  by  traders  of  a  10  per  cent,  duty  to  the  company  for  the 

1  Scott,  op.  cit  ii  3-9 

2  Ibid  10  et  seq. ;  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xlii  et  seq. 

3  Scott,  op.  cit.  ii  36  et.  seq.  *  Ibid  83  et  seq.  s  Ibid  92. 

6  Ibid  229.  »  ibid  20.  *  Ibid  249,  250. 

9  Ibid  260.  10  Ibid  302.  11  Above  186-187,  188. 

12  Ibid  88.  "Ibid  67. 

14  10  William  III.  c.  6  §  2 ;   for  previous  negotiations  with  this  company,  see 
House  of  Lords  MSS.  (N.S.),  iii,  xiii,  xiv  nos.  1274,  1275. 
VOL.  VIII. — 14 


210  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

maintenance  of  its  fortifications.1  In  fact,  the  maintenance  of 
fortifications,  when  this  was  necessary  or  possible,  or  the  main- 
tenance of  consular  agents,  was  the  sole  excuse  for  the  continued 
existence  of  these  companies  ; 2  and,  when  these  duties  were  taken 
over  by  the  state,  these  companies  naturally  disappeared,  or  survived 
only  as  social  clubs.3  Similarly,  the  companies  formed  to  colonize 
gradually  disappeared  when  the  colonies  which  they  founded  had 
become  in  substance  political  societies.4 

On  the  other  hand,  the  privileges  given  to  some  of  these 
companies,  or  the  necessities  or  fortunes  of  their  trade,  secured  to 
some  of  them  a  longer  life.  The  South  Sea  Company  dragged 
out  a  struggling  existence  till  1807  ; 5  and  the  faded  splendours  of 
its  South  Sea  House  survived  long  enough  to  secure  immortality 
in  the  Essays  of  Elia.  The  Hudson's  Bay  Company  served  a 
useful  political  purpose  in  checking  French  influence  in  Canada ; 6 
and  it  obtained  Parliamentary  sanction  by  a  Private  Act  in  1689.7 
Its  usefulness  in  this  direction  continued  till  the  victory  of  Wolfe 
in  1759.  But  even  after  that  event  some  organization  was  neces- 
sary to  conduct  a  trade  with  Indian  tribes ;  and  so,  although  it 
was  a  monopolistic  joint  stock  company,  it  survived  ; 8  and,  having 
abandoned  its  monopolistic  rights  in  1869,9  it  still  survives  as  a 
joint  stock  company.  Similarly,  the  greatest  of  all  these  joint 
stock  companies — the  East  India  Company — survived  the  bitter 
attacks  made  upon  it  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,10  and 

1  9  William  III.  c.  26  ;  House  of  Lords  MSS.  (N.S.)  iii  no.  1292  ;  see  Cunning- 
ham, Industry  and  Commerce  ii  276,  277,  for  its  subsequent  history ;  it  was  finally 
dissolved  by  1  and  2  George  IV.  c.  28. 

2  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  252,  284 ;  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.) 
xli,  xlii ;  cp.  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  97-98  for  a  rebuke  to  the  merchants 
trading  to  Spain  and  Portugal  for  their  "  uncurteous  and  froward  dealing  "  to  the 
consul  appointed  by  the  king ;  see  ibid  397  for  a  dispute  between  the  Turkey  merchants 
and  the  consul  whom  the  Turkey  merchants  paid. 

3  Dr.  Scott  (op.  cit.  ii  69)  tells  us  that  the  Russia  Company  "  continued  to  exist  as 
a  trading  body  till  the  end  of  the  eighteenth  century,  and  as  late  as  1865  furnished  a 
return  to  Parliament  of  certain  dues  it  collected."  Till  the  Russian  Revolution  it 
possessed  its  own  parish  church  in  Moscow  and  its  own  charitable  institutions, 
Quarterly  Review,  July  1925,  153. 

4  See  e.g.  Dr.  Scott's  remarks  on  the  dissolution  of  the  Somers  Islands  Company 
in  1683,  "bid  ii  297 ;  and  cp.  ibid  314,  315,  as  to  the  arrangements  made  by  the 
colonists  with  the  Massachusetts  Bay  Company ;  we  can  see  an  analogous  sequence  of 
events  in  progress  in  America  in  the  dissatisfaction  felt  at  the  conduct  of  the  govern- 
ment of  the  proprietary  colonies,  see  House  of  Lords  MSS.  ii  444,  iv  314,  463.  A 
modern  instance  of  the  workings  of  the  same  process  will  be  found  in  the  events  which 
led  to  the  case  of  In  re  Southern  Rhodesia  [1919]  A.C.  211 ;  Lord  Sumner's  extremely 
able  and  interesting  judgment  gives  us  a  lucid  account  of  the  manner  in  which  this 
development  has  taken  place  in  S.  Africa — an  account  which  is  as  interesting  to  the 
student  of  political  science  as  to  the  constitutional  lawyer. 

8  Cambridge  Modern  History  vi  181,  182. 

6  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  279.  7  Statutes  of  the  Realm  (R.C.)  vi  179. 

8  Cunningham,  op.  cit.  ii  283,  284. 

9  Ibid  279  n.  4 ;  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  xc. 

10  See  Scott,  op.  cit.  ii  135-174,  for  an  account  of  the  troubled  history  of  the  com- 
pany from  1670-1708 ;  for  the  inquiry  in  1695  into  the  bribery  which  the  company  had 
used  to  get  its  charter,  see  House  of  Lords  MSS.  (N.S.)  i  nos.  929,  930. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     211 

continued  to  exist  till  the  middle  of  the  last  century,  mainly 
because  it  was  a  body  whose  governmental  functions  were  becom- 
ing progressive!}'  more  important  than  its  commercial  functions. 
We  have  seen  that  the  minor  governmental  functions  performed  by 
some  of  these  companies  had  led  to  their  survival  in  a  regulated 
form.1  The  increasing  empire  which  the  East  India  Company 
was  acquiring  made  it  necessary  that  the  affairs  of  the  society 
should  continue  to  be  administered  on  a  joint  stock  basis.2 

But  though  some  of  these  earlier  joint  stock  companies  had 
disappeared  or  had  changed  their  form  by  the  end  of  this  century, 
it  was  quite  clear  that  the  joint  stock  principle  had  come  to  stay. 
It  had  become  quite  clear  that  industrial  enterprizes  of  many 
varied  kinds  could  be  initiated  successfully  on  a  joint  stock  basis  ; 
and  an  enormous  extension  was  given  to  the  joint  stock  principle 
when  the  state  used  it  to  borrow  money.  In  1694,  in  return  for 
money  lent  to  it  by  a  group  of  persons,  the  state  incorporated 
this  group  as  a  joint  stock  company  under  the  name  of  the 
Governor  and  Company  of  the  Bank  of  England,  and  empowered 
it  to  conduct  banking  business.  Thus  the  capital  subscribed, 
bearing  the  interest  promised  by  the  state,  was  converted  into  a 
joint  stock  for  the  conduct  of  a  commercial  venture.  The  under- 
lying idea,  as  Dr.  Scott  has  pointed  out,  was  "  the  utilization  of 
capital  lent  to  the  state  as  '  a  fund  of  credit '  on  which  loans 
could  be  raised  by  an  incorporated  body  for  its  trading  opera- 
tions."3 But  this  principle  was  capable  of  development*  If  the 
credit  of  the  state  could  be  converted  into  a  fund  which  could  be 

1  Above  209-210. 

2  See  House  of  Lords  MSS.  (N.S.)  ii  29-56  for  a  discussion  in  1695  as  to  the 
comparative  merits  of  organizing  the  company  on  a  regulated  or  a  joint  stock  basis. 

3 Op.  cit,  i  389  ;  as  Dr.  Scott  says  (ibid  396,  397),  "in  order  to  grasp  the  full 
import  of  the  situation,  it  is  necessary  to  remember  that  the  extensive  utilization  of 
credit  was  new,  and  that  contemporary  observers  noticed  that,  by  this  agency,  business 
had  been  immensely  extended,  and  the  results  achieved  were  viewed  with  amazement. 
.  .  .  The  idea  of  a  fund  of  credit  was  described  as  *  a  mine  of  gold,'  or  as  *  realized 
alchemy.'  .  .  .  Everywhere  when  men  considered  how  enterprizes  had  been  started 
and  had  been  carried  on  successfully  by  the  using  twice  over  of  the  same  wealth,  it 
came  to  be  thought  that  the  process  was  capable  of  infinite  extension. 

*  "  In  Great  Britain,  since  the  Revolution,  this  ideal  had  been  gathering  importance. 
In  addition  to  the  land  bank  schemes  of  1695,  the  finances  of  every  important  com- 
pany had  been  determined  by  it.  Not  only  was  all  the  capital  subscribed  by  the 
members  of  the  Bank  of  England  lent  to  the  State,  but,  in  addition,  a  further  sum  was 
taken  from  the  deposits  of  customers.  Thus  none  of  the  share  capital  was  available 
for  the  business  of  banking,  and  the  loan  made  by  the  Bank  to  the  State  became  in 
fact  a  fund  of  credit,  to  support  the  operations  of  the  institution  .  .  .  the  engrafted 
stock  of  the  Bank  of  England  was  formed  by  the  valuing  of  Government  obligations, 
which  were  selling  at  the  time  at  a  discount  of  about  35  per  cent.,  at  their  nominal 
value.  Apparently  the  operation  was  justified,  for  those  who  converted  their  tallies 
into  engrafted  stock  secured  a  large  profit  by  the  transaction.  Similarly  the  whole 
influence  of  Parliament,  as  affecting  the  East  India  trade,  tended  again  and  again  to 
force  this  branch  of  foreign  commerce  to  depend  solely  on  capital  lent  to  the  State. 
.  .  .  On  three  different  occasions  within  the  space  of  eleven  years  the  East  India  trade 
was  compelled  by  the  state  to  rely  on  a  fund  of  credit,"  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  397-398. 


212  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

thus  profitably  used,  why  should  not  a  company  be  formed  to  take 
over  the  whole  of  the  state  debt  ?  This  company,  if  given  trading 
privileges,  might  be  expected  to  make  large  profits.  The  state 
creditors  would  accept  its  shares  instead  of  their  holdings  in  the 
state  debt,  and  the  company  could  afford  to  pay  the  state  hand- 
somely for  its  privileges.  Thus  in  time  the  state  debt  might  be 
redeemed.  Some  such  ideas  as  these,  coupled  with  schemes  still 
more  ambitious,  inspired  the  grandiose  schemes  of  John  Law  ; l 
and  it  was  these  ideas  which  led  to  the  foundation  of  the  South 
Sea  Company.2 

In  1 7 1 1 ,  when  the  South  Sea  Company  was  originally  founded, 
there  was  a  floating  debt  of  more  than  nine  millions.  It  was  de- 
termined to  incorporate  these  creditors,  and  to  give  them  the 
monopoly  of  the  trade  to  South  America.  The  government 
undertook  to  pay  interest  on  this  debt  at  6  per  cent.,  and  it  was 
to  be  redeemable  after  1716.3  The  company  had  some  success, 
and  in  17 19  a  large  extension  of  this  principle  was  proposed. 
The  company  was  to  take  over  the  whole  of  the  National  Debt, 
except  those  parts  of  it  owed  to  the  Bank  of  England  and  the 
East  India  Company.  The  amount  to  be  thus  taken  over  was 
some  thirty-one  millions.  The  creditors  were  to  be  bought  out, 
or  to  exchange  their  holdings  for  the  company's  stock.  The 
government  was  to  gain,  because  the  debt  was  thereby  made  re- 
deemable, and  the  interest  upon  it  was  to  be  reduced  from  5  to  4 
per  cent  after  1727.4  The  company  considered  that  the  capital 
lent  to  the  state,  the  interest  upon  which  afforded  a  large  revenue 
to  the  company,  was  a  basis  upon  which  immense  sums  might  be 
borrowed  to  extend  indefinitely  the  trade  of  the  company.  "Not 
only  were  there  alluring  prospects  from  the  South  Sea  trade,  but 
the  mere  fact  of  so  large  a  working  capital,  under  prudent  organiz- 
ation, would  render  the  greatest  enterprises  possible.  Further,  the 
close  relations  of  the  company  and  the  Government  must  not  be 
lost  sight  of;  so  that,  in  any  venture  which  required  the  assistance 
of  the  state,  the  most  powerful  support  might  be  counted  on." 5 
Naturally,  the  possession  of  such  privileges  was  considered  to  be 
worth  paying  for.  The  directors  of  the  company,  in  the  first 
instance,  offered  to  pay  the  government  ^3,500,000.  But  the 
Bank  of  England  made  a  higher  offer.  Eventually  the  company, 
unhappily  for  itself  and  happily  for  the  Bank,6  outbid  the  Bank 


1  Cambridge  Modern  History  vi  169-176 ;  cp.  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  398. 
2 "  The  crisis  of   1719-1720   constitutes   simply  the   attempt  to  realise   an   un- 
conscious ideal  of  the  indefinite  expansibility  of  a  fund  of  credit,"  ibid  397. 

3  Cambridge  Modern  History  vi  177,  178. 

4  Ibid  178  ;  cp.  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  408  5  Ibid   iii  307. 
6  Ibid  i  432. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     213 

by  an  offer  of  £7,500,000,  and  by  bribes  offered  to  and  accepted 
by  members  of  the  government  and  the  Legislature.1 

By  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  therefore,  it  was 
recognized  that  the  joint  stock  company  was  a  valuable  instrument 
for  the  promotion  and  working  of  new  industries,  and  for  the 
mobilization  of  national  credit.  On  the  other  hand,  it  had,  as  we 
shall  see,  also  become  clear  that  it  could  be  used  to  perpetrate 
gross  frauds  upon  the  public,  and  to  encourage  wild  speculation 
and  gambling  in  stock  and  shares.  These  new  phenomena 
naturally  had  important  results  both  commercial  and  legal.  With 
these  results  I  must  now  deal. 

(2)  The  commercial  and  legal  consequences  of  the  rise  of  the 
joint  stock  company. 

The  joint  stock  company  met  obvious  needs.  It  gave  to 
capitalists  an  opportunity  for  investment ;  and  it  made  available 
much  capital  which  would  not  otherwise  have  been  employed  in 
trade.2  Then,  too,  it  interested  all  the  wealthier  classes  in  trading 
ventures,  and  so  it  tended  to  make  the  merchants  a  less  exclusive 
class ;  and  this  mixture  of  the  mercantile  and  non-mercantile 
element  in  the  management  of  the  joint  stock  company  conduced, 
as  Dr.  Scott  has  pointed  out,3  to  the  success  of  many  of  the  early 
joint  stock  ventures.  "  In  foreign  trade  or  colonising  much  more 
than  the  specialised  information  of  the  merchant  was  required. 
In  addition,  there  was  needed  something  of  the  imagination  of  the 
pioneer  and  of  the  diplomacy  of  the  statesman  .  .  .  thus  the 
admission  of  a  strong  non-mercantile  element  by  the  joint  stock 
company,  not  only  was  advantageous  in  increasing  the  supply  of 
capital,  but  also  in  strengthening  its  organisation.  From  this 
point  of  view  their  strength  lay  not  so  much  perhaps  in  the  mere 
introduction  of  capitalists  who  were  not  actually  in  trade,  but  in 
the  union  of  these  in  one  body  with  the  mercantile  classes. 
Either  in  isolation  was  imperfect.  The  short-sighted  views  of 
some  of  the  regulated  companies,  and  the  lamentable  ignorance 
displayed  in  the  equipment  of  the  Darien  Company,  are  cases  in 
point  Whereas  the  combination  of  the  specific  and  detailed 
knowledge  of  the  traders,  with  the  broad  outlook  of  the  man  of 
affairs,  tended  towards  a  greater  efficiency."  That  this  combina- 
tion was  so  successfully  made  in  England  is  partly  due  to  the 

1  As  to  the  evidence  for  this  bribery,  which  came  out  in  consequence  of  the 
Parliamentary  inquiry,  see  Scott,  op.  cit.  iii  331-346  ;  the  committee  of  secrecy  re- 
ported that,  while  the  scheme  was  pending,  a  small  committee  of  directors  was 
authorized  to  facilitate  the  passing  of  the  measure,  and  that  they  disbursed  secretly 
£Ii259,325i  ibid  315,  citing  Journals  of  the  House  of  Commons  xix  425-451 ;  the 
East  India  Company  had  resorted  to  similar  methods,  above  210  n.  10. 

3  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  442.  3  Ibid  443,  444. 


214  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

fact  that  the  mercantile  classes  had  never  been  so  separate  from 
other  classes  of  the  community  as  elsewhere ;  and  this  again  was 
due  in  part  to  the  fact  that  mercantile  law  was  becoming  part  of 
the  common  law,  but  chiefly  to  the  absence  of  class  barriers  which 
were  insurmountable.1 

In  the  last  decade  of  the  seventeenth  century,  dealings  in 
shares  of  these  companies  were  so  numerous  that  John  Houghton 
began,  in  1692,  to  publish  a  paper  in  which  the  prices  of  stock 
and  shares  were  recorded.2  We  are  not,  therefore,  surprised  to 
learn  that  "the  mechanism  of  Stock  Exchange  dealings  had  been 
developed  "  ;  that  "  time  bargains  were  well  understood,  and  '  put 
and  call '  options  were  not  unknown  "  ;  and  that  "  the  business  of 
a  stock  broker  was  specialised,  and  a  tariff  of  charges  had  been 
established."3  The  stock  and  share  market  was  beginning  to  be 
familiar  with  its  alternate  booms  and  panics.  Macaulay's  account 
of  the  boom  of  1 692-1695  is  classical.4  Bagehot,5  who  was  a 
banker  and  an  authority  on  such  matters,  said  of  it,  "You  will 
not  find  the  cause  of  panics  so  accurately  explained  in  the  dryest 
of  political  economists — in  the  Scotch  M'Culloch." 

It  was  naturally  in  the  years  of  reaction  which  followed  on  a 
boom,  that  the  shady  side  of  joint  stock  enterprise  forced  itself  on 
the  attention  of  the  public.  A  report  of  the  Commissioners  of 
Trade,  published  in  1696,  accused  the  dealers  in  shares  of  rigging 
the  market,  and  the  promoters  of  companies  of  fraudulently  raising 
the  price  of  shares  by  making  false  statements  as  to  the  prospects 
of  the  company,  and  then  selling  their  holdings  at  a  high  price.0 
The  report  was,  perhaps,  too  sweeping  in  its  condemnation,7 
though  it  is  probable  that  there  were  individual  cases  in  which 
these  or  similar  frauds  had  been  practised.  The  Legislature,  by 
an  act  of  1696-1697,8  attempted  to  regulate  brokers,  and  to  check 
gambling  by  means  of  time  bargains ;    but  nothing  was  done  as 

1  See  vol.  iv  402-407  ;  as  Dr.  Scott  says,  op.  cit.  i  444,  "  this  happy  result  is  to 
be  attributed  in  no  small  degree  to  the  relation  of  classes  in  England,  where  members 
of  different  social  grades  could  work  together  with  the  minimum  of  friction,  and  both 
could  bear  adversity  with  fortitude." 

2  It  is  called  A  Collection  for  the  Improvement  of  Husbandry  and  Trade;  see 
ibid  329,  for  a  description. 

3  Ibid  345.  4  History  of  England  chap.  xix. 
5  Literary  Studies  ii  250. 

6 Journals  of  the  House  of  Commons  xi  595:  "The  pernicious  art  of  stock 
jobbing  hath  of  late  so  perverted  the  end  and  design  of  companies  and  corporations 
erected  for  the  introducing  or  carrying  on  of  manufactures  to  the  private  profit  of  the 
first  projectors,  that  the  privileges  granted  to  them  have  commonly  been  made  no 
other  use  of  by  the  first  procurers  and  subscribers  but  to  sell  them  with  advantage  to 
ignorant  men,  drawn  in  by  the  reputation,  falsely  raised  and  artfully  spread,  concern- 
ing the  thriving  state  of  their  stock.  Thus,  the  first  undertakers  getting  quit  of  the 
company  by  selling  their  shares  for  much  more  than  they  are  really  worth  to  men 
allured  by  the  noise  of  great  profit,  the  management  of  that  trade  and  stock  comes  to 
fall  into  unskilful  hands." 

7  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  358-360.  88  and  9  William  III.  c.  32. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     215 

yet  to  fetter  the  activity  of  the  promoter.  Probably  both  the 
Legislature  and  the  lawyers  were  puzzled.  The  phenomenon  of 
speculation  in  the  shares  of  joint  stock  companies  was,  as  a  com- 
mercial problem,  new  to  the  Legislature,  and,  as  a  legal  problem, 
it  was  equally  new  to  the  lawyers.  This  fact  we  shall  appreciate 
if  we  look  at  the  extreme  poverty  of  the  ascertained  rules  of  law 
applicable  to  commercial  societies,  whether  corporate  or  unincor- 
porated 

In  the  first  place,  the  line  between  corporate  and  unincorporate 
societies  was  generally  disregarded  by  the  projectors  of  companies. 
Bodies  of  persons  joined  together  to  form  a  society,  which  differed 
from  an  incorporated  joint  stock  company  in  no  particular,  except 
in  the  absence  of  a  charter.1  In  the  second  place,  the  powers  of 
an  incorporated  society  acting  under  a  charter  were  by  no  means 
clearly  defined.  Once  having  got  a  charter,  a  society  considered 
itself  free  to  undertake  business  projects  wholly  outside  the  busi- 
ness for  which  it  was  incorporated.2  In  1691  the  York  Buildings 
Company  was  incorporated  to  supply  water  to  London.  But  in 
1 7 1 9  it  sold  its  interest  in  the  waterworks,  and  began  to  deal  in 
lands  forfeited  by  the  Jacobites  in  consequence  of  the  rising  of 
1715.3  This  idea,  that  the  activities  of  an  incorporated  society 
were  not  limited  by  the  terms  of  its  charter,  led  to  a  trade  in 
charters.  Societies  which  wished  to  get  the  privilege  of  incorpora- 
tion at  small  expense,  bought  up  the  charter  of  a  company  which 
had  ceased  to  trade,  and  used  it  to  carry  on  their  own  businesses. 
Thus,  first  a  company  of  merchants  who  proposed  to  lend  money 
on  land  in  Ireland,  and  then  the  banking  partnership  of  Turner 
Casswall  and  Sawbridge  got  possession  of  the  charter  of  a  company 
formed  in  1 69 1  to  manufacture  hollow  sword  blades.  This  bank- 
ing partnership  traded  under  the  name  of  the  Sword  Blade  Com- 
pany. They  acted  as  the  bankers  of  the  South  Sea  Company, 
issued  "  sword  blade  notes "  on  "  sword  blade  bonds,"  and  were 
eventually  proved,  inter  alia,  to  have  falsified  their  books,  and  to 
have  issued  fictitious  notes  to  cover  presents  of  South  Sea  stock  to 
high  officials.4     Similarly,  an  insurance  company  made  use  of  the 


1  Scott,  op.  cit.  i  337,  338,  citing  Houghton,  Collections,  No.  98,  15th  June  1694  ; 
as  Dr.  Scott  says,  probably  the  preoccupation  of  the  government  in  the  war  allowed 
these  practices  to  escape  notice ;  "  as  it  was,  no  obstacle  was  placed  in  the  way  of 
those  who  wished  to  start  any  enterprise  by  means  of  a  joint  stock,  and  it  was  left  to 
the  founders  of  each  venture  to  prescribe  the  constitution  under  which  it  was  to  work  "  ; 
see  the  preamble  to  the  Act  of  1719,  6  George  I.  c.  18  §  18,  below  220. 

2  For  the  legal  theory  at  the  back  of  this  idea  see  chap,  vi  §  2. 

3  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  cxxvi,  cxxvii ;  Scott,  op.  cit.  iii 
418-434. 

4  Select  Charters  of  Trading  Companies  (S.S.)  cxiii,  cxiv ;  Scott,  op.  cit.  iii  435- 
442  ;  the  best  account  of  the  doings  of  this  banking  partnership  is  contained  in  a  note 
to  the  Preface  of  vol.  lxxi  of  the  Revised  Reports  at  pp.  viii-ix. 


216  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

charters  of  the  Mines  Royal  and  the  Mineral  and  Battery  Works.1 
The  South  Sea  Company,  in  1720,  instigated  proceedings  against 
some  of  these  companies,  with  the  result  that  their  charters  were 
forfeited ; 2  and  it  was  this  very  rash,  and,  in  the  circumstances, 
impudent  action  on  the  part  of  that  company,  which  began  the 
panic  which  ruined  it.3  These  proceedings  established  the  rule 
that  the  activities  of  a  company  were  limited  by  the  terms  of  its 
charter ;  and  that  it  could  only  use  the  powers  conferred  by  its 
charter  in  furtherance  of  the  business  for  the  carrying  on  of  which 
it  had  been  incorporated.4  But  it  would  be  difficult  to  point  to 
any  previous  authority  in  which  this  elementary  principle  had  been 
precisely  laid  down ;  and,  in  fact,  in  the  Parliamentary  inquiries  of 
this  period,  the  directors  of  some  of  these  companies  cited  in  sup- 
port of  their  proceedings  the  opinions  of  eminent  counsel  whom 
they  had  consulted.5  In  the  third  place,  accounts  were  often  kept 
in  a  very  irregular  manner  ; 6  and  as  "  the  idea  of  capital  as  some- 
thing which  should  be  kept  intact  was  unknown,"  7  no  very  clear 
notions  prevailed  as  to  what  parts  of  the  gains  of  a  company  were 
properly  divisible  as  profit.     In  fact,   "  the  payment  of  dividends 

1  Scott,  op.  cit.  iii  398. 

2  Ibid  i  425-427;  as  Dr.  Scott  says  (ibid  iii  325),  "  while  the  South  Sea  Company 
was  within  its  rights  in  raising  this  question,  its  action  was  most  injudicious.  ...  It 
might  well  have  been  argued  that  since  the  directors,  who  professed  themselves  ag- 
grieved by  companies  acting  under  obsolete  charters,  employed  as  their  banker  an  as- 
sociation that  worked  under  a  grant  for  the  making  of  hollow  sword  blades,  they  had 
condoned  the  offence.  Indeed,  when  one  considers  the  many  indirect  practices  of  the 
directors,  both  in  obtaining  and  applying  their  own  Act  of  1720,  it  was  the  height  of 
effrontery  to  have  raised  the  question." 

3  "  It  may  have  been  some  consolation  to  the  companies  attacked  by  the  South  Sea 
directors  to  know  that  the  stroke  directed  against  them  had  recoiled  with  crushing  force 
upon  the  aggressors.  Before  the  issue  of  the  writ  South  Sea  stock  had  stood  at  850,  a 
month  later  it  was  as  low  as  390,"  ibid  i  427. 

4  This  is  made  quite  clear  by  some  opinions  of  the  Attorney-General  given  in  1719, 
which  are  cited  in  the  Journals  of  the  House  of  Commons  xix  at  pp.  345  and  349.  In 
the  first  of  these  opinions  he  said :  "  The  transactions  stated  in  the  report  to  have  been 
carried  on  for  the  insurance  of  ships  and  merchandise  under  colour  or  pretence  of  the 
charters  aforesaid  [the  Mines  Royal  and  the  Mineral  and  Battery  Works]  and  in  the 
names  of  the  supposed  corporations  are  illegal  and  unwarrantable  .  .  .  those  charters, 
being  granted  for  the  particular  ends  specified  and  limited  therein,  not  giving  sufficient 
authority  to  the  corporations  thereby  erected,  if  they  were  existing,  to  carry  on  a  busi- 
ness or  employment  of  so  publick  a  nature  as  that  of  insurance  of  ships  and  merchan- 
dise, and  which  is  wholly  foreign  to  the  design  of  those  incorporations. "  In  the  second 
of  these  opinions,  dealing  with  the  land  speculations  of  the  York  Buildings  Company, 
he  said  :  "  The  corporation  created  by  the  Act  of  Parliament  above  recited  was  so  in- 
stituted for  the  particular  purposes  therein  specified ;  and  though  the  power  therein 
given  to  purchase  lands  is  not,  by  express  words,  restrained  to  any  particular  annual 
value,  yet  by  a  reasonable  construction,  the  exercise  of  that  power  ought  to  be  governed 
and  limited  by  the  purposes  for  which  the  corporation  was  erected." 

5  Sir  John  Williams  deposed  "that  they  had  consulted  and  had  the  opinion  of 
several  eminent  counsel  that  they  might  insure  ships  by  virtue  of  the  charters  for  the 
Mines  Royal  [and]  the  Mineral  and  Battery  Works;  and  that  two  of  the  said  counsel 
are  Sir  Robert  Raymond  and  Mr.  Reeves,"  Journals  of  the  House  of  Commons  xix 
344  ;  see  chap,  vi  §  2  for  an  explanation  of  this  view. 

6 Scott,  op.  cit.  i  158,  159,  7  Ibid  60. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     217 

out  of  capital  was  quite  usual."1  In  the  fourth  place,  there  was 
no  clear  law  as  to  the  manner  in  which  claims  against  a  company, 
which  had  been  dissolved  or  had  amalgamated  with  another  com- 
pany, should  be  settled.  Persons  who  had  claims  against  the  dis- 
solved or  amalgamated  company  often  found  it  difficult  to  realize 
them.2 

Nor  was  the  law  as  to  unincorporated  partnerships  in  a  much 
better  state.  We  shall  see  that  the  courts  were  beginning  to  arrive 
at  some  rules  as  to  the  order  in  which  the  joint  and  separate  pro- 
perty of  the  partners  could  be  made  liable  for  the  debts  of  the  firm, 
and  the  debts  of  the  individual  partner,  in  a  case  where  one  of  the 
partners  was  bankrupt3  It  was  well  recognized  that  the  maxim 
jus  accrescendi  inter  mercatores  locum  non  habet  applied  to  partners  ; 4 
so  that,  though  a  surviving  partner  could  sue  a  partnership  debtor 
or  be  sued  by  a  partnership  creditor  without  joining  the  executor 
of  the  deceased  partner,5  the  executor  was  entitled  to  the  deceased's 
share  of  the  partnership  assets,6  and  was  liable  to  pay  the  deceased 
partner's  share  of  the  partnership  debts.7  It  was  also  well  recog- 
nized that  the  partners  were  agents  for  one  another,  and  that,  in 
matters  falling  within  the  scope  of  the  partnership  business,  they 
could  bind  one  another.8  The  convenience  of  the  machinery  of 
the  court  of  Chancery  for  the  taking  of  accounts,  the  common  law 
rule  that  actions  between  the  partners  and  the  firm  or  between  two 
firms  having  a  common  membership  were  impossible,9  the  possibility 
of  getting  discovery,10  and  injunctions  against  anticipated  breaches 

1  Op.  cit.  Dr.  Scott  says  that  in  the  sixteenth  century  "  there  was  no  need  of  a  term 
to  describe  the  whole  outiay.  As  yet  the  company  stood  in  this  respect  too  near  the 
partnership  for  the  want  of  a  capital  account  to  be  felt.  The  idea  of  capital  as  some- 
thing which  should  be  kept  intact  was  unknown,  and  very  much  later  the  payment  of 
dividends  out  of  capital  was  quite  usual.  In  fact  .  .  .  the  temporary  joint  stock  made 
this  method  of  procedure  unavoidable.  As  the  goods  brought  home  were  sold  the  ad- 
venturers received  payments  pro  rata  ;  and  when  the  voyage  had  been  a  success  they 
obtained  more  than  they  had  paid  in,  if  it  was  a  failure  they  might  get  less." 

2  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  586-587 — the  Merchant  Adventurers,  hav- 
ing been  requested  to  surrender  their  charter,  said  they  were  willing  to  do  so,  but 
"  whereas  by  this  resignacion  of  our  charters,  wee  shalbe  disenabled  to  recover  any 
debtes  due  unto  the  bodie  of  our  Company,  and  thereby  want  meanes  to  pay  what  wee 
owe  to  other  men,  wee  therefore  humbly  pray  your  honours  that  such  power  and 
authority  may  be  given  us,  whereby  wee  may  not  only  collect  such  sommes  as  are 
and  shalbe  due  to  the  body,  but  also  make  a  cessement  upon  the  now  Bretheren  of  this 
Company  for  the  better  satisfaction  of  those  debtes,  which  are  owing  unto  others  by  the 
same" ;  S.P.  Dom.  (1676-1677)  34,  35 — a  petition  to  the  Council  by  an  agent  of  the 
Royal  Adventurers  Company,  which  had  sold  its  assets  to  the  Royal  Africa  Company, 
stating  that,  "  though  the  members  of  the  new  company  consist  mostly  of  persons  who 
were  members  of  the  old  company,"  he  cannot  get  his  claims  satisfied. 

3  Below  242-243.  4Jeffereys  v.  Small  (1683)  1  Vern.  217. 
'Martin  v.  Crompe  (169S)  1  Ld.  Raym.  340;  a  principle  apparently  applied  also 

to  co-factors,  Holstcomb  v.  Rivers  (1669)  1  Eq.  Cas.  Ab.  5. 

8  Ibid.  1  Lane  v.  Williams  (1693)  2  Vern.  292. 

9  Lane  v.  Williams  (1693)  2  Vern.  277 ;  Pinkney  v.  Hill  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  175. 

9  Above  202  n.  5. 

10  Estwick  v.  Conningsby  (1682)  1  Vern.  118. 


218  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

of  the  partnership  agreement,1  were  all  beginning  to  bring  partner- 
ship cases  under  the  jurisdiction  of  equity.  But  the  court  of 
Chancery  had  as  yet  only  just  begun  to  lay  the  foundations  of  the 
modern  law. 

Obviously  this  state  of  the  law  tended  to  increase  the  risk  of 
fraud,  because  it  left  the  promoters,  directors,  or  members  of 
commercial  societies  corporate  or  unincorporate,  and  the  dealers 
in  their  shares,  very  free  to  act  as  they  pleased.  Obviously,  also, 
these  risks  were  very  much  increased,  when  the  state  gave  an 
impetus  to  the  joint  company,  by  using  it  as  a  means  to  borrow 
money  from  its  subjects. 

We  have  seen  that  the  state  was  prepared  to  incorporate  its 
creditors,  and  to  give  to  the  company  so  incorporated  certain 
privileges  in  return  for  a  loan  ; 2  and  that  this  was  the  basis  upon 
which  the  Bank  of  England  was  founded.3  But  we  have  seen 
that  later  this  idea  was  extended.  The  South  Sea  Company  was 
prepared  to  take  over  the  greater  part  of  the  National  Debt  in 
return  for  trading  privileges,  and  to  pay  the  state  handsomely  for 
the  opportunity  of  doing  so,  in  expectation  that  the  capital  and 
revenue  thus  acquired  would  be  a  "  fund  of  credit,"  which  would 
enable  it  to  conduct  an  enormous  trade,  and  earn  correspondingly 
enormous  profits.4  Now,  no  doubt  the  growth  of  the  system  of 
lending  money  to  the  state  had  many  and  obvious  advantages. 
It  gave  to  the  individual  a  safe  form  of  investment.  It  increased 
the  stability  of  the  state,  because  it  gave  to  a  large  number  of  its 
citizens  a  direct  pecuniary  interest  in  that  stability — in  fact,  it  had 
an  effect  upon  the  stability  of  the  state  precisely  similar  to  the 
effect  which  the  distribution  of  the  spoils  of  the  monasteries  had 
in  Henry  VIlI.'s  reign  upon  the  stability  of  the  Reformation 
settlement.5  On  the  other  hand,  the  methods  adopted  to  raise  the 
money,  the  bribery  which  accompanied  the  negotiations  with  the 
South  Sea  Company,  and  the  manipulation  of  the  existing  debt 
under  the  influence  of  exaggerated  ideas  of  what  could  be  accom- 
plished by  means  of  a  "  fund  of  credit,"  gave  such  an  impetus  to 
rash  speculation  that  the  boom  of  171 9-1 720,  and  the  ensuing 
panic,  surpassed  anything  that  had  yet  been  known  in  the  financial 
world.      All  classes  followed  the  example  of  the  Government,6  and 

1  Spence,  Equitable  Jurisdiction  i  666.  2  Above  188-1S9. 

3  Ibid.  4  Above  212-213.  5  Vol.  iv  37. 

6  J)r.  Scott  (op.  cit.  iii  351,  352)  points  out  that,  in  the  case  of  the  South  Sea 
Company,  the  state  had,  through  the  connivance  of  responsible  ministers,  practically 
sanctioned  this  gamble.  As  he  says  :  "  Whatever  may  be  one's  judgment  on  the 
ethics  of  modern  speculation,  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries,  the  State 
not  only  encouraged  but  often  represented  such  adventures  of  capital  as  a  part  of  the 
duty  of  a  patriot.  In  this  connection  it  is  only  necessary  to  refer  to  the  advertise- 
ment of  the  State  lotteries  of  the  period.  There  is  abundant  testimony  that  any  who 
spoke  or  wrote  against  the  company  when  the  fever  was  at  its  height  were  held  to  be 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     219 

tried  to  find  a  short-cut  to  riches  by  investing  in  companies  which 
promised  immediate  wealth  on  easy  terms;  and  the  promoters 
and  the  directors  of  companies,  unrestrained  by  any  effective  rules 
of  law,  were  left  practically  free  to  gull  the  public  as  they  pleased. 
In  order  to  remedy  these  obvious  evils,  for  which  the  Legislature 
itself  was  largely  responsible,  it  passed  a  measure  which  influenced 
for  more  than  a  century  the  history  of  commercial  societies  in  this 
country. 

(3)  The  Bubble  Act  and  its  effect  on  the  development  of 
company  and  partnership  law. 

After  considering  a  good  deal  of  evidence  as  to  the  promotion 
and  administration  of  many  of  the  companies  which  had  sprung 
up  during  this  period  of  speculation,  the  House  of  Commons  came 
to  the  following  resolution  : l — "  That  for  some  time  past  several 
large  subscriptions  having  been  made  by  great  numbers  of  persons 
in  the  city  of  London  to  carry  on  public  undertakings,  upon  which 
the  subscribers  have  paid  in  small  proportions  of  their  respective 
subscriptions,  though  amounting  on  the  whole  to  great  sums  of 
money ;  and  that  the  subscribers  having  acted  as  corporate  bodies 
without  any  legal  authority  for  their  so  doing,  and  thereby  drawn 
in  several  unwary  persons  with  unwarrantable  undertakings,  the 
said  practices  manifestly  tend  to  the  prejudices  of  the  public  trade 
and  commerce  of  the  kingdom."  In  other  words,  the  House  of 
Commons  neglected  the  deeper  causes  of  the  panic — the  encourage- 
ment to  speculation  given  by  the  Government's  connection  with  the 
South  Sea  scheme,2  the  corruption  of  the  Ministry  and  of  members 
of  the  Legislature,3  the  extravagant  notions  entertained  of  the 
powers  of  a  fund  of  credit,4  the  facilities  for  fraud  and  negligence 
given  by  the  absence  of  any  sort  of  legal  control  over  the  activities 
of  promoters  and  directers  ; 5  and  they  concentrated  their  attention 
on  .one  cause  only — the  extension  of  the  joint  stock  system  by  the 
manner  in  which  societies,  which  were  not  incorporated,  usurped 
corporate  form,  and  the  consequent  growth  of  the  "pernicious  art 
of  stock-jobbing."  6  What  was  needed  was  an  Act  which  made  it 
easy  for  joint  stock  societies  to  adopt  a  corporate  form,  and,  at  the 

disaffected.  So  that,  so  far  from  the  speculator  being  blamed  for  his  rashness  at  this 
time,  it  is  to  be  remembered  that  all  information  that  would  enlighten  him  was 
discouraged,  while  he  was  overwhelmed,  and  too  often  carried  away,  by  data  designed 
to  mislead." 

1  Journals  of  the  House  of  Commons  xix  351. 

2  Above  218  n.  6.  3  Above  213. 

4  Above  211-212  ;  as  Dr.  Scott  says  (op.  cit.  i  437) :  "  Politicians  sometimes  find 
a  remedy  for  their  mistakes,  but  they  rarely  have  the  candour  to  make  a  public 
recantation  of  the  principles  which  caused  those  mistakes  to  be  made.  Everyone  at 
the  end  of  1720  blamed  the  mechanism  which  had  shown  the  disorder  of  credit ;  no 
one  seized  upon  the  fallacy  that  had  been  the  true  cause  of  the  distemper." 

5  Above  215-217.  6Scott,  op.  cit.  i.  436,  437. 


220  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

same  time,  safeguarded  both  the  shareholders  in  such  societies 
and  the  public  against  frauds  and  negligence  in  their  promotion 
and  management.  What  was  passed  was  an  Act  which  deliber- 
ately made  it  difficult  for  joint  stock  societies  to  assume  a  corporate 
form,  and  contained  no  rules  at  all  for  the  conduct  of  such  societies, 
if,  and  when,  they  assumed  it. 

The  Act *  began  by  repeating  in  substance  the  resolution  to 
which  the  House  of  Commons  had  come.  It  set  out  the  evils 
which  had  arisen  from  the  starting  of  dangerous  undertakings  on 
a  joint  stock  basis  with  a  transferable  stock,  from  the  unlawful 
assumption  of  corporate  form,  and  from  the  trade  in  charters 
which  had  recently  been  carried  on.2  It  then  condemned  as 
illegal  all  such  undertakings  to  the  prejudice  of  trade,  and  sub- 
scriptions, assignments,  transfers,  and  other  things  for  furthering 
such  undertakings  ;  the  acting  or  presuming  to  act  as  a  corporate 
body ;  the  raising  of  a  transferable  stock,  or  the  assigning  of  such 
stock  without  authority  either  by  Act  of  Parliament  or  by  charter  ; 
acting  under  any  charter  formerly  granted  by  the  crown  for  pur- 
poses other  than  those  expressed  in  the  charter,  or  under  an  obsolete 
or  forfeited  charter.3  It  was  provided  that  these  acts  should  be 
deemed  to  be  public  nuisances,4  that  the  persons  guilty  thereof 
should  incur  the  penalties  provided  by  the  statute  of  Praemunire,5 
that  merchants  injured  by  them  could  sue  for  treble  damages,6 
and  that  brokers  dealing  in  the  shares  of  such  undertakings  should 
be  liable  to  a  penality  of  .£500. 7  The  Act  was  not  to  extend  to 
undertakings  established  before  June  24,  171 8 — they  were  to 
be  left  to  the  common  law.8  Henceforth  there  was  to  be  no 
confusion  between  a  corporate  and  a  non-corporate  commercial 
society.  Henceforth  the  privilege  of  possessing  a  transferable 
stock,  which  brokers  or  jobblers  could  manipulate,  was  to  belong- 
only  to  a  corporate  society. 

Nor  were  these  results  wholly  objectionable.  It  is  not  good 
for  the  state  that  large  societies  which  are  not  corporations,  and 
yet  assume  to  act  as  corporations,  should  be  allowed  to  exist. 
Such  societies  are  much  more  difficult  to  regulate  than  a  corpora- 
tion. A  corporation  has  received  a  privilege  from  the  state,  and, 
in  return  for  that  privilege,  it  can  be  submitted  to  such  rules  as 
may  seem  necessary  to  protect  both  its  members  and  the  public. 
Its  existence  is  well  known,  and  inquiries  can  easily  be  made  into 

1  6  George  I.  c.  18  §§  18-22 ;  for  the  leading  decisions  on  the  Act,  see  Lindley, 
Law  of  Companies  (5th  ed.)  130-132  ;  see  also  R.  v.  Webb  (181 1)  14  East  406. 

2  §  18  preamble.  3  §  18.  4  §  19. 
BIbid.                                                        6§20.                                     7§2I. 

8§  22.  This,  of  course,  would  make  corporations  trading  nnder  obsolete  charters, 
or  trading  in  a  manner  not  allowed  by  their  charters,  still  liable  to  legal  proceedings, 
above  215-216 ;  whether  at  common  law  societies  with  a  transferable  stock  were  illegal 
is  more  doubtful,  below  221. 


COMPANIES  AND  PARTNERSHIPS     221 

its  conduct.  It  is  difficult  to  regulate  an  unincorporated  society, 
because,  if  it  is  proposed  to  subject  it  to  legal  liability,  it  is  apt  to 
dissolve  into  its  component  parts,  and  leave  the  injured  person  to 
the  impossible  remedy  of  suing  a  large  number  of  persons  who, 
individually,  are  not  worth  suing ;  nor  is  it  easy  to  ascertain  the 
manner  in  which  its  affairs  are  conducted.  What  was  objection- 
able in  the  Act  was  the  hindrances  which  it  threw  in  the  way  of 
the  assumption  of  a  corporate  form.  The  Act,  as  Dr.  Scott  has 
pointed  out,  stopped  the  development  of  the  joint  stock  system. 
«'  It  became  both  difficult  and  costly  to  obtain  the  necessary  legal 
authorisation  for  the  starting  of  a  new  enterprise  needing  a  large 
capital.  In  one  that  might  have  been  established  with  a  moderate 
outlay,  which  for  any  reason  it  was  desirable  to  collect  from  a 
large  number  of  persons,  the  trouble  and  cost  proved  prohibitive. 
Therefore,  for  upwards  of  a  century,  industry  was  deprived  of  the 
advantages  of  a  certain  amount  of  capital  which  would  otherwise 
have  been  available."1 

When  the  Act  was  repealed  in  1825  2  interesting  questions 
arose,  analogous  to  those  which  arose  after  the  repeal  of  the 
Combination  Acts,3  as  to  whether  the  offences  created  by  the  Act 
were  also  offences  at  common  law,  and  in  consequence  unaffected 
by  the  repealing  Act.  On  this  point  there  was  a  considerable 
divergence  of  judicial  opinion,  because  the  common  law  had,  as 
we  have  seen,4  no  very  definite  rules  upon  the  subject.  The  cases 
of  the  earlier  part  of  the  nineteenth  century  decided  that  though, 
possibly,  the  assumption  of  the  status  of  a  corporation  without 
authority,5  and  certainly  the  formation  of  a  company  which 
attempted  to  defraud  the  public,  or  otherwise  of  a  dangerous  or 
mischievous  character,  were  illegal  acts  ;  6  the  mere  formation  of  a 
joint  stock  company "  with  a  transferable  stock  8  was  not  illegal ; 
and  this  view  is  probably  historically  correct9 

1  Op.  cit.  i  438.  2  4  George  IV.  a  94. 

J  Vol.  ii  470-471.  *  Above  215-217. 

5  Duvergier  v.  Fellows  (1828)  5  Bing.  at  p.  267  ;  and  cp.  Harrison  v.  Heathorn, 
{1845)  6  Man.  and  Gr.  at  pp.  137, 138 ;  but  (ibid  at  p.  107)  Tindal  C.J.  seems  to  doubt 
whether  this  was  an  offence  at  common  law ;  cp.  Lindley,  Law  of  Companies  (5th 
ed.)  131  n.  c. 

6Blundell  v.  Winsor  (1837)  8  Sim.  601,  as  explained  by  In  re  The  Mexican 
and  South  American  Co.  (1859)  27  Beav.  at  pp.  481,  482  ;  Lindley,  op.  cit  133. 

7  Walburn  v.  Ingilby  (1833)  1  My.  and  K.  at  p.  76. 

8  Garrard  v.  Hardey  (1843)  5  Man.  and  Gr.  471;  Harrison  v.  Heathorn  (1843) 
6  Man.  and  Gr.  81 ;  but  it  appears  that  Lord  Eldon  thought  otherwise  ;  see  Kinder 
v.  Taylor,  cited  in  th«  argument  of  Duvergier  v.  Fellows  (1828)  5  Bing.  at  pp.  261, 
262. 

9  As  Tindal,  C.J.,  said  in  Harrison  v.  Heathorn,  at  p.  140:  "The  raising  of 
transferable  shares  of  the  stock  of  a  company  can  hardly  be  said  to  be  of  itself  an 
offence  at  common  law ;  no  instance  of  an  indictment  at  common  law  for  such  an 
offence  can  be  shown,  the  raising  of  stocks  with  transferable  shares  being,  indeed,  a 
modern  proceeding ;  and  the  very  great  particularity  with  which  it  is  described  in  the 
statute  seems  to  show  that  it  was  an  offence  created  by  the  statute  only."     It  would 


222  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

The  history  of  commercial  societies  after  the  passing  of  the 
Bubble  Act,  the  causes  which  led  to  its  repeal,  the  rise  of  the 
limited  company,  and  the  enormous  development  of  the  joint  stock 
principle  which  ensued,  belong  to  the  modern  history  of  this  branch 
of  commercial  law. 

We  must  now  turn  to  the  law  of  agency,  the  development  of 
which  was  a  necessary  consequence  of  the  rise,  both  of  the  modern 
mechanism  of  negotiable  instruments  and  banking,  and  of  these 
commercial  societies  corporate  and  unincorporate. 

§  5.  Agency 

Primitive  systems  of  law  are  ignorant  of  a  law  of  agency.  The 
parties  to  acts  in  the  law  must  execute  them  in  person.1  But  so 
soon  as  the  law  begins  to  develop,  this  primitive  principle  begins 
to  yield  at  different  points  to  practical  necessities.  The  Salman 
was  an  agent  for  a  particular  purpose — the  transference  of  property 
in  accordance  with  the  directions  which  he  had  received.2  In  later 
law  the  feoffee  to  uses  was  an  agent  for  a  somewhat  analogous 
purpose.3  The  attorney  was  an  agent  for  purposes  of  litigation  ;  4 
and  the  clauses  in  commercial  and  other  documents,  which  allowed 
the  bearer  or  the  creditor's  nominee  to  sue,  were  designed  to  evade 
the  strict  rules  of  primitive  law  as  to  the  employment  of  agents 
for  this  purpose.5 

Gradually  the  common  law  came  to  recognize  a  law  of  agency 
both  for  the  acquisition  of  chattels  personal,  and  for  the  making 
of  contracts. 

The  development  of  the  actions  of  detinue  and  trespass  on  the 
case  gave  the  beneficiary  an  adequate  remedy,  when  chattels 
personal  had  been  conveyed  to  another  person  to  his  use.6  On  the 
other  hand,  though  a  man  could  appoint  an  attorney  or  agent  to 
convey  or  receive  hereditaments  or  chattels  real,  he  had  no  adequate 
remedy  against  a  person  who  held  such  property  on  his  account, 
until  the  rise  of  the  use  and  the  equitable  trust. 7 

We  begin  to  see  the  rise  of  agents  for  the  purpose  of  contract 
at  an  early  date.     At  first  these  agents  were  found  chiefly  in  the 

seem  that  a  transferable  share,  being  a  chose  in  action,  would  have  been  as 
impossible  at  common  law  as  a  limitation  of  the  liability  of  the  shareholders,  see 
Walburn  v.  Ingilby  (1833)  1  My.  and  K.  at  p.  76 ;  but  that  neither  the  attempt  to 
make  the  share  transferable  nor  the  attempt  to  limit  liability  would  make  the 
association  illegal ;  on  the  whole  subject  see  Lindley,  op.  cit.  132-135. 

1 "  Dans  le  tres  ancien  droit,  les  actes  juridiques  doivent  etre  accomplis  par 
rint^resse"  lui-meme ;  c'est  la  une  consequence  de  leur  caractere  formaliste ;  les 
solennit£s  ou  les  paroles  qu'ils  supposent  impliquent  son  intervention ;  elles  n'auraient 
pas  de  sens  si  elles  gmanaient  d'un  tiers,"  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1442. 

2  Vol.  iii  563-565  ;  vol.  iv  410-412.  3  Ibid  411. 

4  Vol.  ii  315-317.  6  Above  116-117. 

6  Vol.  iii  425-426,  428,  443-444  ;  above  88.  7  Vol.  iv  413-414. 


AGENCY  223 

higher  ranks  of  society  and  in  public  law.  "  The  king  ever  since 
John's  day  has  been  issuing  letters  of  credit  empowering  his  agents 
to  borrow  money,  and  to  promise  repayment  in  his  name.  A  great 
prelate  will  sometimes  do  the  like.  .  .  .  Among  the  clergy  the 
idea  of  procuration  was  striking  root ;  it  was  beginning  to  bear 
fruit  in  the  domain  of  the  public  law ;  the  elected  knights  and 
burgesses  must  bring  with  them  to  parliament  'full  powers'  for 
the  representation  of  the  shires  and  boroughs." l  But  in  the  early 
thirteenth  century  the  appointment  of  agents  for  this  purpose  was 
not  common  ;  and  it  would  seem  that  agents  informally  appointed 
or  appointed  by  implication  were  hardly  recognized.2  However,  it 
was  not  long  before  it  gained  recognition ;  and  the  fact  that  the 
practice  spread  somewhat  readily  in  the  course  of  the  thirteenth 
century,  is  due  to  the  two  allied  influences  of  mercantile  necessity 
and  the  canon  law.  From  an  early  date  the  records  of  the  fair 
courts  show  that  some  sort  of  commercial  agency  must  perforce  be 
recognized  ; 3  and,  during  the  fourteenth  and  fifteenth  centuries,  the 
development  of  trading  companies,  which  must  necessarily  act 
through  agents,  helped  its  further  development.4  All  through  the 
Middle  Ages  the  ideas  of  the  canon  law  in  this,  as  in  other  branches 
of  commercial  law,5  made  for  its  easier  recognition.  As  Maitland 
has  shown,  "the  legal  deadness  of  the  monk  favoured  the  growth 
of  a  law  of  agency  "  ;  6  and  the  corporate  bodies  of  monks,  like  the 
corporate  bodies  of  merchants,  needed  agents.  Thus  the  canon 
law  acquired  some  rules  upon  this  branch  of  the  law ;  and  the 
merchants  could  borrow  and  apply  these  rules  to  the  agents  whom 
they  employed7 

Thus,  in  the  course  of  the  mediaeval  period,  the  ideas  that 
it  is  possible  to  make  a  contract  through  an  agent,  and  that  it 
is  possible  for  a  man  to  ratify  a  contract  made  on  his  behalf 
through  an  agent,  were  fully  recognized  by  the  common  law.8 
The  common  law  also  recognized  that  on  such  contracts  the 
principal  and  not  the  agent  was  liable,9  not  only  when  the  agent 
had  express  authority  to  do  the  particular  act,  but  also  when  he 

1  P.  and  M.  ii  225. 

*  Bracton's  Note  Book,  case  873,  cited  P.  and  M.  ii  225  n.  6. 

3  Vol.  v  m-112.  «  Above  193  seqq. 

5Vol.  v  80-83.   .    m  «P.  and  M.  ii  226  n.  1. 

7  Bnssaud,  op.  tit.  ii  1444, «« la  situation  des  procureurs  aux  negoces  (par  opposition 
aux  procureuers  aux  causes,  proces)  est  reglementee  par  voie  d'emprunt  aux  regies  du 
droit  romain  et  du  droit  canon  (Sexte  5,  12,  68,  72  (3))." 

«  See  vol.  iii  528-530  for  the  application  of  these' principles  to  the  liability  of  the 
husband  for  the  wife's  debts ;  and  see  generally  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability 
n  446-448.  °  J 

9Y.B.  11  Hy.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  53  per  Thirning;  and  this  rule  was  followed  by 
equity,  see  Graham  v.  Stamper  (1692)  as  reported  in  1  Eq.  Cas.  Ab.  308-^00 ;  cp. 
2  Vern.  146,  and  the  note. 


224  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

acted  within  the  scope  of  an  authority  to  do  acts  of  a  particular 
kind.1 

During  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  it  was  begin- 
ning to  be  seen  that  certain  classes  of  agents  were  more  closely 
connected  with  commercial  law.  In  the  books  of  mercantile  law 
written  by  merchants  or  civilians,  it  is  clear  that  two  chief  classes 
of  mercantile  agents  are  emerging — brokers  and  factors. 

Brokers,  Malynes  tells  us,  were  intermediaries,  through  whom 
two  persons  were  brought  into  contractual  relations.  They  had 
been  long  known  in  the  city  of  London,  where  provisions  had 
been  made  for  their  regulation.2  He  approves  the  practice  of 
dealing  through  brokers — thereby  "  many  differences  are  prevented, 
which  might  arise  between  man  and  man  in  their  verbal  contracts  ; 
for  the  testimony  of  a  sworn  broker  and  his  book  is  sufficient  to 
end  the  same.  And  moreover  it  is  many  times  a  cause  that 
factors  and  servants  deal  more  faithfully  for  their  masters  in 
buying  and  selling  of  all  commodities,  or  in  moneys  by  exchange, 
knowing  their  evidence  is  extant  against  them."  3  But  he  says  that 
brokers  were  seldom  used  in  England4 — a  statement  which  is 
probably  an  exaggeration,  at  any  rate  in  London.  At  the  end 
of  the  seventeenth  century,  however,  they  were  well  enough 
known ;  and  it  is  clear  that  a  distinct  class  of  brokers,  dealing  in 
bills  of  exchange  and  in  stocks  and  shares,  were  beginning  to 
emerge.5  Public  opinion  credited  these  brokers  with  making 
combinations  and  confederacies  to  raise  or  lower  the  price  of 
stock  ; 6  and  though  perhaps  more  blame  was  placed  upon  their 

^.B.  8  Ed.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  9  (p.  n),  "si  jeo  command  mon  servant  d'achater 
certein  biens,  ou  jeo  face  un  home  mon  factor  et  mon  atturney  pur  achater  marchandise 
etc.,  en  ce  cas  s'il  achat  marchandise  d'un  home,  jeo  sera  charge  per  tiel  contract, 
comment  que  les  biens  ne  unques  veigue  en  maines,  et  comment  que  jeo  n'ay  unques 
notice  de  ceo,  et  le  cause  est  pur  ce  que  jeo  don  tiel  power  a  eux,  et  ce  fuist  mon  foly 
de  issint  faire,"  per  Pigot ;  cp.  27  Ass.  p.  133  pi.  5  ;  Doctor  and  Student  Bk.  II. 
c.  42  f.  137a. 

2  Vol.  ii  387 ;  there  are  many  cases  turning  upon  the  misdeeds  of  those  sworn 
brokers  in  the  early  Rolls  of  Mayor's  Court  which  run  from  1298-1307,  see  pp.  28, 
32-33,  and  complaints  of  persons  acting  as  brokers  without  being  sworn,  ibid  7-9,  37. 
Malynes,  Lex  Mercatoria  Bk.  I.  c.  xxxix,  says,  "  no  broker  should  be  admitted  unless 
he  were  sworn,  and  upon  affidavit  or  certificate  made  by  some  principal  merchants  of 
his  sufficiency  and  behaviour,  and  to  put  sureties  for  his  true  and  good  demeanour 
amongst  Merchants,  according  to  the  custom  of  London  "  ;  see  2  James  I.  c.  21 
preamble ;  further  regulations  of  pawnbrokers  were  made  by  proclamation  in  1630, 
Tudor  and  Stuart  Proclamations  i  no.  1613  ;  they  were  to  be  registered  and  enter 
into  a  bond  of  £100 ;  for  a  proposed  bill  of  1678  to  regulate  pawnbrokers,  which 
was  passed  by  the  House  of  Commons  and  dropped  in  the  House  of  Lords,  see 
Hist.  MSS.  Com.  gth  Rep.  App.  Pt.  ii  122  no.  616. 

3  Malynes,  loc.  cit.  4  Ibid. 

5  8,  9  William  III.  c.  32  Preamble. 

6  "  Whereas  diverse  brokers  and  stock  jobbers  or  pretended  brokers  have  lately 
set  up  and  carried  on  most  unjust  practices  and  designs  in  selling  and  discounting 
of  talleys,  bank  stock,  bank  bills,  shares  and  interests  in  joint  stocks  .  .  .  and 
have  .  .  .  unlawfully  combined  and  confederated  themselves  together  to  raise  or 
fall  from  time  to  time  the  value  of  such  talleys,  bank  stock,  and  bank  bills  as  may 


AGENCY  225 

shoulders  than  was  just,1  they  no  doubt  sometimes  helped  to 
manipulate  the  market  in  their  own  interest.  At  any  rate  the 
Legislature  in  1696- 1697  thought  it  necessary  to  regulate  their 
business. 

The  Act 2  did  not  apply  to  brokers  for  the  purchase  and  sale 
of  cattle,  corn  or  other  provisions,  and  coal.  It  did  apply  to 
brokers  for  the  purchase  and  sale  of  all  other  merchandise,  for 
taking  up  money,  for  negotiating  bills  of  exchange,  and  for  the 
sale  and  discount  of  tallies,  bank  stock,  bank  bills,  and  shares  in 
joint  stock  companies.3  No  person  was  to  act  as  a  broker  in 
London,  Westminster,  or  within  the  Bills  of  Mortality,  without 
a  licence  from  the  Lord  Mayor ; 4  and  no  broker,  even  though 
so  licensed,  could  deal  in  tallies  or  stock  secured  upon  funds 
granted  by  Parliament,  unless  licensed  by  the  Treasury.5  A 
broker,  on  being  admitted,  must  take  an  oath  to  do  his  duty, 
and  give  a  bond  for  its  performance ; 6  and  their  names  and  ad- 
dresses were  to  be  published.7  They  must  keep  a  broker's  book, 
and  enter  in  it  all  contracts  made  by  them  within  three  days  of 
their  date.8  They  must  not  take  more  than  10s.  per  cent, 
brokerage ; 9  and  penalties  were  imposed  on  a  broker  who  took 
more,  or  who  dealt  for  himself  in  the  exchange  of  money,  or  who 
bought  stock  or  shares  to  sell  again.10  In  order  to  discourage 
dealings  in  speculative  options,  it  was  provided  that  every  bargain 
to  give  a  man  liberty  to  accept  or  refuse  shares  should  be  void 
unless  it  was  exercisable  within  three  days.u  The  number  of 
brokers  was  limited  to  one  hundred.12  It  is  clear  from  this  Act 
that  brokers  were  beginning  to  take  an  important  place  in  the 
commercial  world.  But  as  yet  their  legal  position  is  ill  defined. 
There  are  few  if  any  cases  concerning  them  in  the  reports. 
Comyns,  in  his  Digest,  cites  none. 

The  broker  was  an  independent  person :  the  factor  was 
essentially  an  employe.     The  broker  could  not  be  mistaken  for  a 

be  most  convenient  for  their  own  private  interest  and  advantage,  which  is  .  .  . 
extremely  prejudicial  to  the  public  credit  of  this  kingdom  and  to  the  trade  and 
commerce  thereof,  and  .  .  .  may  ruin  the  credit  of  the  nation  and  endanger  the 
government  itself,"  ibid;  cp.  Luttrell's  Diary  iii  528,  529  for  some  manipulations 
of  the  price  of  guineas ;  and  see  generally  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  i  358. 

1  Mr.  Scott  says  that,  though  the  war  tended  to  produce  great  instability  ot 
prices,  "it  is  remarkable  that  quotations  display  so  little  of  the  see-saw  movement 
due  to  market  manipulation,  but  on  the  contrary  follow  well-defined  lines  of  move- 
ment, the  causes  of  which  can  generally  be  traced";  hence  he  thinks  that  "the 
blame  laid  on  stock  jobbing  was  to  a  large  extent  undeserved,"  ibid  i  358-360. 

3  8,  9  William  III.  c.  32  §  14.  3  8,  9  William  III.  c.  32  Preamble. 

4§x-  ..  5§i5- 

•  §  2 — in  addition  to  the  oaths  of  allegiance  and  supremacy. 

7  §  4 ;  §  8  required  them  to  carry  a  silver  medal  which  must  be  shown  to  the 
parties  at  the  conclusion  of  all  contracts. 

8  §6.  »§7.  io§9. 
u  §  10  ;  above  214.                                                             13  §  g# 

VOL.   VIII. — 15  k 


226  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

servant  of  his  principal :  the  factor  at  this  period  was,  in  the  eye 
of  the  common  law,  very  much  in  the  position  of  a  servant.1 
Nevertheless,  according  to  the  practice  and  usage  of  the 
merchants,  the  factor  differed  essentially  from  a  servant.  "  The 
difference,"  says  Malynes,  ' '  between  a  factor  and  a  servant  con- 
sisteth  chiefly  in  this,  that  a  factor  is  created  by  merchant's 
letters,  and  taketh  salary  or  provision  of  factorage :  but  a  servant 
or  an  apprentice  is  by  his  master  entertained,  some  receiving  wages 
yearly  and  some  others  without  wages.  A  factor  is  bound  to 
answer  the  loss  which  happeneth  by  overpassing  or  exceeding  his 
commission ;  whereas  a  servant  is  not,  but  may  incur  his  master's 
displeasure."  2  Malynes  then  gives  certain  rules  as  to  the  adjust- 
ment of  accounts  between  merchant  and  factor,  as  to  keeping 
within  the  limits  of  his  commission,  as  to  his  liability  to  account 
for  any  gain  made  by  the  use  of  his  master's  credit,  as  to  his 
liability  for  false  entries  at  the  custom  house,  as  to  his  liability  for 
the  loss  of  or  damage  to  goods  entrusted  to  him,  as  to  his  duties 
in  relation  to  letters  of  credit,  bills  of  exchange,  the  freighting  of 
ships,  and  the  insuring  of  ships  or  cargoes.3  Molloy's  chapter  on 
factors  does  not  add  anything  very  material  to  the  information 
given  by  Malynes.4 

The  information  given  by  Malynes  and  Molloy  no  doubt  sum- 
marizes existing  mercantile  practice.  But  as  yet  this  practice  was 
very  little  known  to  the  English  courts  of  law  and  equity.  The 
cases  which  turn  upon  the  relations  of  merchant  and  factor  are 
very  few  in  number,  and  deal  only  with  one  or  two  isolated  points 
on  the  fringe  of  the  subject.  Thus  we  get  a  few  cases  in  the 
common  law  courts,  which  turn  on  the  applicability  of  the  actions 
of  account  or  debt,5  on  the  liability  for  non-payment  of  duties  at 
the  custom  house,6  and  on  the  interpretation  of  the  bonds  which 
factors  gave  to  perform  their  duties  carefully  and  honestly.7  In 
Chancery  we  get  some  cases  turning  upon  liability  for  erroneous 
entries  at  the  custom  house,8  and  on  the  administration  of  the 

1  In  Southcote's  Case  (1601)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  84a  Coke  explains  that  a  factor,  un- 
like a  carrier,  is  not  liable  if,  without  his  fault,  the  goods  trusted  to  him  are  stolen, 
"  for  if  a  factor  (although  he  has  wages  and  salary)  does  all  that  which  he  by  his 
industry  can  do,  he  shall  be  discharged,  and  he  takes  nothing  upon  him,  but  his  duty 
is  as  a  servant  to  merchandize  the  best  that  he  can,  and  a  servant  is  bound  to  perform 
the  command  of  his  master." 

2  Malynes,  op.  cit.  Bk.  I.  c.  xvi.  3  Ibid. 
4  De  Jure  Maritimo  et  Navali  (4th  ed.)  Bk.  III.  cap.  viii. 

8  See  e.g.  Core's  Case  (1537)  Dyer  20a ;  The  Earl  of  Lincoln  v.  Topcliff  (1599) 
Cro.  Eliza.  644. 

8  William  Lewson  v.  Kirk  (16 11)  Cro.  Jac.  265. 

7  Sheppard  v.  Maidstone  (1713)  10  Mod.  144  ;  The  African  Company  v.  Mason 
(1715)  10  Mod.  227. 

8  Smith  v.  Oxenden  (1663)  1  Cases  in  Chancery  25;  Borr  v.  Vandall  (1663)  ibid 
30 ;  Knipe  v.  Jesson  (1666)  ibid  76 — in  which  the  extraordinary  rule  was  laid  down 
that,  if  the  factor  could  succeed  in  defrauding  the  customs  of  a  foreign  country,  he 
could  keep  the  profit,  as  he  had  run  the  risk. 


AGENCY  227 

estate  of  a  deceased  factor  which  comprised  assets  belonging  to  the 
merchant  or  vice  versa.1  In  this  period  we  get  little  else.2  In 
fact,  during  the  greater  part  of  it,  this  branch  of  the  common  law 
has  been  least  of  all  affected  by  the  customs  and  rules  of  the  law 
merchant. 

Perhaps  the  best  proof  of  this  fact  is  the  refusal  of  the  common 
law  to  draw  any  distinction  between  the  law  of  principal  and  agent, 
and  the  law  of  master  and  servant.  In  common  speech,  no  doubt, 
both  in  the  seventeenth  century  and  in  our  own  day,  the  terms 
principal  and  agent  connote  commerce,  and  the  terms  master  and 
servant  domestic  service ; 3  but,  except  in  so  far  as  special  statutes 
have  put  particular  classes  of  agents  upon  a  footing  of  their  own, 
the  common  law  still  treats  these  two  branches  of  law  as  funda- 
mentally identical.  If  in  England  commercial  law  had  ever  come 
to  be  administered  by  special  commercial  courts,  the  law  of  com- 
mercial agency  might  have  come  to  be  a  branch  of  the  law  quite 
distinct  from  the  law  of  master  and  servant.  The  fact  that 
commercial  law  came  to  be  administered  by  the  common  law 
courts,  has  prevented  any  such  distinction  from  growing  up.4 
Coke,  as  we  have  seen,5  regarded  the  factor  as  a  servant ;  and 
Blackstone  dealt  with  the  law  of  agency  in  his  chapter  on  Master 
and  Servant.6 

The  result  was  that  the  development  of  the  law  of  commercial 
agency  was  very  slow.  We  shall  see  that  the  courts,  during  the 
greater  part  of  this  period,  contented  themselves  with  applying  the 
strict  rules  of  the  mediaeval  common  law."  Except  in  those  cases 
in  which,  from  motives  of  public  policy,  a  more  extended  liability 
was  allowed,8  a  master  was  only  liable  for  the  acts  of  his  agent  if 
he  had  actually  ordered  him  to  act,  or  if  he  had,  by  words  or 
conduct,  subsequently  ratified  his  acts.  And  this  conception  was, 
as  we  shall  see,  applied,  as  in  the  mediaeval  period,  both  to  the 
contracts  made  and  to  the  torts  committed  by  the  agent.  The  cases 
of  Barton  v.  Sadock  and  Southern  v.  How  illustrate  this  point 

In  the  case  of  Barton  v.   Sadock,9  the  plaintiff,  a  merchant, 

1  Chapman  v.  Derby  (1689)  2  Vein.  117 — claim  by  a  factor  on  the  estate  of  a 
deceased  merchant ;  Burdett  v.  Willett  (1708)  2  Vern.  638 — claim  by  a  merchant  on 
tne  estate  of  a  deceased  factor. 

2  We  have  seen,  vol.  i  505 ;  vol.  v  150  n.  2,  that  the  Council  occasionally  inter- 
fered on  equitable  grounds  to  redress  cases  of  hardship  caused  by  a  principal's  or  an 
agent's  fraud — but  these  cases  do  not  carry  us  very  far. 

3  Thus,  Locke,  Two  Treatises  of  Government  Bk.  II.  chap,  vii  §  85  uses  the  terms 
in  this  sense. 

*"  There  has  never  been  a  time  when  cases  on  master  and  servant  were  not  cited 
as  authority  in  the  law  of  principal  and  agent,  and  vice  versa"  Street,  Foundations  of 
Legal  Liability  ii  454. 

*  Above  226  n.  1.  s  Comm.  i  c.  xiv. 

7  Vol.  iii  382-385  ;  below  251-252,  472-473. 

8  Vol.  iii  385-387  ;  below  476-477.  »  (1610)  1  Bulstr.  103. 


228  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

brought  an  action  of  account  against  the  defendant,  his  factor,  for 
certain  jewels  delivered  by  the  plaintiff  to  the  defendant  to  trade 
with  beyond  the  sea.  The  defendant  had  sold  the  jewels  to  Mulle- 
shake,  the  king  of  Barbary,  for  ^45  ;  but  he  had  not  yet  received 
the  money.  It  was  held  that  he  was  liable  to  the  plaintiff. 
Fleming,  C.J.,  said,1  "In  cases  of  authorities  given  to  one  (as  in 
this  case  here)  to  sell  anything,  as  a  factor,  in  the  due  execution 
of  this  authority,  he  ought  presently  upon  the  sale  thereof  to  have 
and  receive  quid  pro  quo,  otherwise  he  doth  not  well  perform  the 
authority,  thus  to  him  given,  neither  ought  he  upon  the  sale  there- 
of, to  give  him  any  further  time,  or  day  of  payment,  but  as  he 
delivers  the  one,  so  he  ought  then  presently,  at  the  same  time,  to 
receive  the  money  for  the  same  for  which  it  was  sold."  2  In  the 
case  of  Southern  v.  How 3  the  defendant  was  the  owner  of  certain 
counterfeit  jewels.  He  sent  them  to  his  factor  in  Barbary  to  be 
sold.  The  factor,  through  the  plaintiff,  sold  them  to  the  king  of 
Barbary  for  £800,  telling  him  that  they  were  good  jewels ;  and 
the  ;£8oo  was  paid  over  in  due  course  to  the  plaintiff.  When  the 
king  discovered  that  they  were  counterfeit,  he  imprisoned  the 
plaintiff  till  he  repaid  him  the  ^"800.  On  these  facts  the  plaintiff 
brought  his  action  on  the  case  against  the  defendant.  Judgment 
was  given  for  the  defendant,  chiefly,  the  report  tells  us,  on  the 
ground  that  the  master  did  not  command  the  factor  to  conceal  the 
fact  that  the  jewels  were  counterfeit.4  This  case  thus  illustrates 
the  fact  that,  at  this  period,  as  in  the  mediaeval  period,  the 
principle  applied  to  the  liability  of  the  master  for  the  torts  of  his 
servant  was  the  same  as  that  applied  to  his  liability  for  his 
servant's  contracts.  In  both  cases  there  must  be  a  particular 
authority  to  do  the  act  complained  of.  Such  cases  as  these  show 
that,  if  the  factor  was  to  be  protected  from  personal  liability,  he 
must  be  able  to  show  that  authority  had  been  given  to  him  in 
very  wide  terms.5  It  was  only  very  occasionally  that  the  criminal 
equity  administered  by  the  Council 6  and  the  Star  Chamber 7 
relaxed  these  rules. 

At  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  it  was  becoming  obvious 
that  these  rules  were  quite  inadequate.  In  fact  the  exigencies  of 
commerce  compelled  all  the  courts  to  reconsider  the  principles  of 

1  At  p.  104.  2  This  case  was  followed  in  1676,  Anon.  2  Mod.  100. 

3  (1618)  Cro.  Jac.  468.  4  At  p.  470. 

5  As  Malynes  says,  op.  cit.  Bk.  I.  c.  xvi,  if  you  have  a  good  factor,  "  all  com- 
missions given  unto  him  may  be  ample,  with  addition  of  these  words,  dispose,  do,  and 
deale  therein  as  if  it  were  your  own." 

6  Dasent  vii  204  (1564-1565) — a  master  is  ordered  to  produce  his  servant  guilty  of 
an  affray  or  to  go  to  prison. 

7  Reportes  del  Cases  165 — it  was  ruled,  that,  "  where  one  commands  his  servant 
to  enter  on  certain  land,  and  to  take  distress  peaceably,  and  he  enters  with  many 
others  riotously,  the  master  is  a  rioter." 


BANKRUPTCY  229 

this  branch  of  the  law.  The  court  of  Chancery  was  beginning 
to  apply  the  principles  of  equity  to  the  solution  of  some  of  its 
problems.  Thus  in  one  case  it  applied  the  analogy  of  trustee  and 
cestui  que  trust  to  the  relations  between  a  factor  and  his  principal ; x 
and  in  another  it  ruled  that  payment  by  a  principal  to  his  agent 
did  not  necessarily  discharge  his  debt  to  the  creditor.2  Then,  too, 
it  was  clear  that  the  very  limited  delictual  liability  of  the  principal 
for  his  agent's  torts  urgently  demanded  revision ;  and  in  this  part 
of  the  law  we  shall  see  that  certain  civil  law  rules,  applied  by  the 
court  of  Admiralty  to  the  relations  of  shipowners,  masters,  and 
merchants,  were  taken  over  by  Holt,  C.J.,  and  the  common  law 
courts,  and  used  by  them  as  a  technical  justification  for  this 
extension.3  Probably  Holt's  decisions  upon  this  branch  of  the 
law  of  agency  were  largely  instrumental  in  preserving  it  for  the 
common  law.  If  the  common  lawyers  had  refused  to  extend  it  to 
meet  obvious  needs  it  might  very  possibly  have  been  developed 
mainly  by  the  court  of  Chancery. 

§  6.  Bankruptcy 

In  many  early  systems  of  law  the  obligation  of  the  debtor  is 
personal  in  a  very  literal  sense — the  body  of  the  debtor  can  be 
taken  by  the  creditor.4  In  all  early  systems  of  law  each  creditor 
is  left  to  pursue  his  own  remedy.  There  is  no  machinery  by 
which  the  creditors  as  a  body  can  collectively  enforce  their  claims. 
But  as  soon  as  industry  and  commerce  begin  to  develop,  these 
primitive  ideas  must  be  modified.  Whenever  it  is  possible  the 
creditor  enforces  his  rights  against  the  property  and  not  against 
the  person  of  the  debtor ;  to  prevent  fraud,  and  to  facilitate  the 
equal  treatment  of  all  the  creditors,  a  procedure  by  which  creditors 
can  collectively  enforce  their  claims  is  developed ;  and  generally 
some  distinction  is  drawn  between  a  debtor  who  is  unable  to  pay 
by  misfortune,  and  a  debtor  who  is  unable  to  pay  by  reason  of 
his  cwn  recklessness  or  fraud. 

These  developments  had  taken  place  in  the  Italian  commercial 
cities  in  the  Middle  Ages.5  They  had  adapted  to  their  own  use 
the  bankruptcy  procedure  of  the  Roman  law  (  Venditio  Bonorum), 
under  which  the  whole  property  of  the  debtor  was  divided  equally 
among  his  creditors.6     At  the  same  time  they  had  adopted  also 

1  Burdett  v.  Willett  (1708)  2  Vern.  638. 

2  Speerman  v.  Degrave  (1709)  2  Vern.  643.  *  Below  250-253,  473-475. 

*  "  Dans  le  tres  ancien  droit,  c'est  la  personne  du  debiteur,  son  corps,  qui  r^pond 
avant  tout  du  pavement  de  sa  dette ;  par  extension,  ses  meubles  en  repondent  aussi, 
car  mobilia  ossibus  inherent,"  Brissaud,  op.  cit,  ii  1462. 

9  Ibid  1465  ;  for  Genoa  see  Leges  Genvenses,  Mon.  Hist.  Pat  xviii  cols.  574, 
657-659. 

6  For  the  Roman  Law  of  Venditio  Bonorum  see  Girard,  Droit  Roman  1013-1017; 
Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1465  n.  3,  notes  that  the  law  of  the  Italian  towns  diverged  from 


230  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  modified  procedure  of  the  Cessio  Bonorum,  under  which  a 
debtor,  who  was  unable  to  pay  by  misfortune,  could  escape  arrest, 
and  get  discharged  from  his  liabilities  by  giving  up  all  his  property.1 
From  Italy  these  forms  of  procedure  gradually  spread  to  other 
countries  during  this  period,  and  Malynes 2  gives  us  some  account 
of  them. 

In  England,  as  in  other  countries,  a  similar  development  took 
place  during  this  period.  But  in  order  to  understand  the  reasons 
why  in  England,  as  elsewhere,  this  development  was  necessary,  I 
must  make  a  short  digression,  and  explain  what  remedies  were 
open  at  common  law  to  a  judgment  creditor  against  the  chattels 
or  person  of  his  debtor.3 

The  two  writs  by  which,  at  common  law,  a  judgment  creditor 
could  realize  his  claim  were,  either  the  writ  of  fieri  facias,  under 
which  the  sheriff  was  directed  to  cause  to  be  made  from  the  goods 
and  chattels  of  the  debtor  the  sum  adjudged  to  be  due  to  the 
creditor ;  or  the  writ  of  levari  facias,  under  which  he  was  directed 
to  levy  it  out  of  the  goods  and  the  profits  of  the  land.4  By 
neither  of  these  writs  could  the  body  of  the  debtor  be  taken  ;  and 
it  is  "  not  a  little  remarkable  that  the  common  law  knew  no  pro- 
cess whereby  a  man  could  pledge  his  body  or  liberty  for  payment 
of  a  debt,  for  our  near  cousins  came  very  naturally  by  such  a 
process,  and  in  old  times  the  wite  theow  may  very  often  have  been 
working  out  by  his  labours  a  debt  that  was  due  to  his  master. " 5 
Perhaps  the  reason  is  to  be  sought  in  the  fact  that  the  common 
law,  under  the  influence  of  the  ideas  drawn  from  the  mature 
Roman  law,  had  shaken  off  the  very  primitive  ideas  as  to  the 
strictly  personal  character  of  liability  for  debt,  which  lead  archaic 
systems  of  law  to  the  conclusion  that  the  seizure  of  the  debtor's 
body  is  the  only  proper  mode  of  enforcing  his  obligation  to  pay. 

But,  though  the  earliest  systems  of  personal  execution  rest  upon 
very  primitive  ideas,  the  law  has  at  no  time  been  able  to  dispense 
wholly  with  the  power  of  restraining  the  debtor's  person  in  the 


the  classical  Roman  law  in  the  following  particulars :  (a)  cessation  of  payment  is  a 
presumption  of  insolvency  and  an  act  of  bankruptcy ;  (b)  transactions  entered  into  a 
short  time  previous  to  the  bankruptcy  are  rendered  void ;  (c)  a  majority  of  the  creditors 
can  give  time  to  the  debtor  and  allow  him  to  resume  control  over  his  business. 

1  Girard,  op.  cit.  1013  n.  4 ;  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1471,  tells  us  that  in  France  it 
early  made  its  appearance  in  the  customs  of  the  south,  and  also  in  the  north  in  the 
second  half  of  the  thirteenth  century  ;  in  a  small  tract  of  1582  entitled  "  A  newe  order 
for  Banqueroupts,"  an  account  is  given  of  a  decree  of  the  Parlement  of  Paris  as  to  the 
conditions  on  which  a  cession  of  goods  could  be  made. 

2  Op.  cit.  Bk.  I.  c.  xliv  ;  Bk.  III.  c.  xii,  pp.  293-294. 

3  For  his  remedies  against  the  debtor's  land  see  vol.  iii  131-132. 

4  P.  and  M.  ii  594  ;  Harbert's  Case  (1585)  3  Co.  Rep.  at  pp  11b,  12a ;  Bl.  Comm. 
iii  281. 

8  P.  and  M.  ii  594;  for  Reeves's  erroneous  view  to  the  contrary  see  C.J.  Fox's 
article  in  L.L.R.  xxxix  46-47,  48-52. 


BANKRUPTCY  231 

last  resort.  At  all  times  there  will  be  persons  whose  morality  is 
so  much  below  the  average  commercial  morality  of  the  age,  that 
they  do  not  scruple  to  take  advantage  of  the  credit  which,  in 
reliance  upon  the  existence  of  that  commercial  morality,  is  given 
to  them.  If  it  is  advantageous  to  commerce  that  the  standard  of 
commercial  morality  should  be  high,  and  that  credit  should  be 
given,  it  is  necessary  to  bring  home  to  such  persons,  in  the  only 
way  in  which  they  will  feel  it,  the  consequences  of  their  conduct. 
It  is  true  that  the  imprisonment  of  a  debtor,  who  is  unable  or  un- 
willing to  pay  his  debt,  will  not  necessarily  give  the  creditor  his 
money ;  but  it  will  tend  to  stop  such  abuses  of  confidence.  At 
the  same  time  it  is  a  means  of  coercion  which  requires  to  be 
regulated  carefully  ;  and  in  most  systems  of  law  it  is  recognized 
that  it  should  be  used  sparingly  and  in  the  last  resort 

The  common  law  soon  discovered  that  it  could  not  do  without 
this  method  of  execution.  In  the  case  of  one  class  of  debts  it  was 
permitted  by  statute  from  an  early  date.  It  was  provided  in 
1285  that  a  debtor  by  statute  merchant  could  be  arrested.1  But 
in  most  cases  this  form  of  execution  was  gradually  and  indirectly 
introduced,  by  means  of  changes  in  the  process  of  the  courts,  and 
changes  in  and  developments  of  the  forms  of  action  The  manner 
of  its  introduction  was  as  follows  : — From  the  first  a  writ  of  capias 
ad  respondendum  had  been  a  part  of  mesne  process  in  actions  of 
trespass  vi  et  armis.2  In  the  thirteenth  century  this  writ  was 
extended  to  actions  of  account ; 3  in  the  fourteenth  century  to 
actions  of  debt,  detinue,  and  replevin ; 4  and  at  the  beginning  of 
the  sixteenth  century  to  actions  on  the  case.5  It  had  been  laid 
down  in  Edward  IIL's  reign  that  when  a  writ  of  capias  ad 
respondendum  lay  to  get  the  defendant  before  the  court,  a  writ  of 
capias  ad  satisfaciendum  would  lie  to  obtain  execution  of  the 
judgment6  The  result  was  that  in  practically  every  case  a  creditor 
could  take  his  debtor's  body  in  execution.  But,  if  he  elected  to 
adopt  this  remedy,  as  he  usually  did,  no  other  mode  of  execution 
was  open  to  him." 

Constraint  of  the  debtor's  person  thus  became  in  England  a 
more  general  method  of  execution  than  in  many  other  countries  in 
Europe.  Largely  because  it  was  introduced  in  this  indirect  way, 
a   mode   of  execution    which    required,   and    in    most    countries 

1 13  Edward  I.  st  3 ;  vol.  iii  132.  2  P.  and  M.  ii  592. 

3  52  Henry  III.  c.  23  ;  13  Edward  I.  c.  n.  4  25  Edward  III.  c.  17. 

5 19  Henry  VII.  c.  9 ;  as  Blackstone  says,  Comm.  iii  282,  by  virtue  of  these  and 
other  statutes  a  capias  may  be  had  upon  almost  every  species  of  complaint. 

•Y.BB.  40  Ed.  III.  Pasch.  pi.  28;  49  Ed.  III.  Hil.  pi.  5  ;  cp.  Harbert's  Case 
(1585)  3  Co.  Rep.  at  p.  12a ;  3  Salk.  286. 

7  See  21  James  I.  c.  24  ;  Bl.  Comm.  iii  415. 


232  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

received,  careful  limitation  and  regulation  from  the  Legislature,1 
was  almost  entirely  unregulated.  The  results  can  be  read  in  the 
pages  of  Dickens  ;  and,  long  before  Dickens  wrote,  the  abuses  and 
the  inadequacy  of  the  different  modes  of  execution  known  to  the 
common  law  had  aroused  attention. 

As  early  as  Henry  VIII. 's  reign  it  had  become  obvious  that 
the  machinery  of  the  common  law  was  wholly  inadequate  to  the 
needs  of  the  merchants  of  the  sixteenth  century.  Henry  Brink  low, 
citizen  and  mercer  of  the  city  of  London,  who  wrote  in  the  later 
years  of  Henry  VIII.  's  reign,2  shows  us  that  the  merchants  were 
beginning  to  complain  that  English  law  lagged  behind  the  laws  of 
other  mercantile  communities.  "Another  thing  very  nedeful  to 
be  loked  upon  is  this,  that  when  any  merchant  or  other,  by  losse 
of  goodes,  by  fortune  of  the  sea,  evel  servantys,  evyl  detters,  by 
fyre,  or  other  wyse,  come  to  an  after  deale,  and  not  able  to  pay 
his  credyte  at  his  due  tyme,  but  by  force  of  povertye  is  constrayned 
to  demand  longer  tyme — than  ye  have  a  parcyell  lawe  in  making 
of  tachmentys,3  first  come,  first  servyd ;  so  one  or  ij  shall  be  all 
payd,  and  the  rest  shal  have  nothyng.  And  comonly  even  the 
rych  shal  have  the  foredeale  therof  by  this  tachement,  to  the  gret 
dammage  and  oppressyon  of  the  pore.  For  lyghtly  the  rich  have 
the  first  knowlege  of  soch  things.  Wherfor,  in  that  case  it  were  a 
godly  way  to  make  it  in  Ingland,  as  it  is  in  dyverse  contryes, 
whan  any  such  chance  falleth,  that  than  the  most  in  nomber  of 
the  credytors  and  most  in  somme,  shal  bynde  the  rest  to  doo  and 
gyve  lyke  tyme  as  doo  the  most  of  the  credytors.  And  if  it  be 
duly  found  that  the  man  be  so  farre  at  after  deale,  that  he  be  not 
able  to  pay  his  whole  credite  in  reasonable  tyme,  that  than  the 
lawe  may  bynd  them  that  every  man  may  have  pound  and  pound 
alyke,  as  farre  as  his  goodys  will  goo,  leavyng  him  somewhat  as 
the  lawe  shall  thynck  good.  And  this  lawe  shal  be  both 
neyhborly  and  godly." 

Brinklow  in  this  passage  points  to  one  serious  defect  in  the 
law — its  unfairness  to  creditors.  Equally  obviously  it  was  unfair 
to  debtors.  Debtors  might  be  either  honest  and  unfortunate,  or 
dishonest ;  and  in  both  cases  the  law  was  inadequate.  To  shut 
up  an  honest  but  unfortunate  debtor  in  prison,  where  he  lived  on 


1  For  its  regulation  in  French  Law  see  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  |ii  1469-1471  ;  the 
regulation  began  as  early  as  1254 — "  Saint  Louis,  en  1254,  P"1  des  dispositions  qui 
auraient  du  la  faire  disparaitre,  mais  qui  eurent,  du  moins,  pour  rdsultat  d'accentuer 
son  caractere  subsidiaire  et  d'en  faire  une  voie  d'exe"cution  exceptionnelle " ;  cp. 
Malynes,  op.  cit.  293-294. 

2  Complaynt  of  Roderyck  Mors  (E.E.T.S.)  c.  17.  Brinklow  was  originally  a  Grey 
Friar.  He  became  a  mercer  and  citizen  of  London,  married,  and  died  in  1546.  He 
was  a  strong  Protestant,  as  his  works  show.      This  book  was  written  about  1542. 

3  I.e.  attachments. 


BANKRUPTCY  233 

charity  or  at  his  own  expense,  or  died  of  starvation,1  inflicted 
much  hardship  on  the  debtor  without  any  benefit  to  the  creditor. 
On  the  other  hand,  if  the  debtor  was  a  dishonest  person,  who  had 
become  insolvent  through  his  own  fault,  he  would  very  likely  be 
able  to  secrete  some  of  his  ill-gotten  gains,  and  live  in  comparative 
comfort  in  prison,  till  he  forced  his  creditors  to  some  sort  of 
compromise.2 

The  need  for  better  laws  was  met  in  two  ways — firstly  by  the 
jurisdiction  of  the  Council,  and  secondly  by  the  Legislature.  And 
during  this  period  we  can  distinguish  two  quite  distinct  lines  upon 
which  the  Council  and  the  Legislature  proceeded.  Firstly  the  law 
was  modified  in  favour  of  the  unfortunate,  and  secondly  it  was 
sharpened  as  against  the  dishonest,  debtor.  We  shall  see  that 
it  was  from  the  second  of  these  lines  of  development  that  the 
bankruptcy  laws  spring. 

(i)  Modifications  in  favour  of  the  unfortunate  debtor. 

(i)  The  activities  of  the  Council. 

On  behalf  of  the  honest  but  unfortunate  debtor  the  Council 
repeatedly  and  actively  interfered.  Sometimes  it  arranged  or  en- 
forced a  composition  with  his  creditors.  That  such  compositions 
were  usual  in  the  middle  of  the  sixteenth  century  can  be  seen  from 
a  precedent  for  a  deed  of  this  kind  in  Phayre's  book ; 3  but  their 
effect  was  liable  to  be  nullified  by  obstinate  creditors.  The  Council 
applied  pressure  to  such  creditors,  and  ordered  creditors  to  make 

1  What  may  be  perhaps  called  the  strictly  mediaeval  view  of  the  position  cf  the 
imprisoned  debtor  is  to  be  found  in  Dive  v.  Manningham  (1551)  Plowden  at  p.  68,  "  If 
one  be  in  execution  he  ought  to  live  of  his  own,  and  neither  the  plaintiff  nor  the  sheriff 
is  bound  to  give  him  meat  or  drink,  no  more  than  if  one  distrains  cattle  and  puts  them 
in  a  pound.  .  .  .  And  if  he  have  no  goods  he  shall  live  of  the  charity  of  others,  and  if 
others  will  give  him  nothing,  let  him  die,  in  the  name  of  God,  if  he  will,  and  impute 
the  cause  of  it  to  his  own  fault,  for  his  presumption  and  ill-behaviour  brought  him  to 
that  imprisonment "  ;  clearly  this  state  of  the  law  was  quite  unsuited  to  the  economic 
conditions  of  the  sixteenth  century ;  cp.  Brinklow,  op.  cit.  c.  12,  for  a  strong  indictment 
of  the  hardships  inflicted  on  prisoners  at  this  period ;  at  the  end  of  the  period  the 
Legislature  intervened  ;  14  Elizabeth  c.  5  §  38,  and  39  Elizabeth  c.  3  §  13  provided  for 
the  assessment  of  a  county  rate  for  the  relief  of  these  prisoners  ;  but  it  would  appear 
from  Malynes,  op.  cit.  294-298,  that  its  intervention  was  not  very  effective ;  and  this  is 
borne  out  by  a  petition  of  the  poor  prisoners  in  the  Fleet  prison  and  elsewhere,  who 
pointy  out  that  "  in  no  other  country  is  perpetual  imprisonment  the  punishment  ot 
debt,"  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  3rd  Rep.  App.  26  ;  for  later  legislation  see  below  234-235. 

"  For  one  illustration  see  Hudson,  Star  "Chamber  65,  66,  cited  vol.  i  505  ;  and  for 
another  see  a  petition  to  the  House  of  Lords,  Hist  MSS.  Com.  4th  Rep.  App.  5  in 
which  it  was  alleged  that  a  debtor  by  collusion  was  still  getting  a  large  part  of  his 
income,  "  and,  though  nominally  a  prisoner  in  the  Fleet  these  fourteen  years,  yet  by 
Habeas  Corpus  or  otherwise,  has  liberty  to  travel  where  he  pleases  with  his  own  man 
as  his  keeper,  and  regards  not  payment  of  his  debts." 

3  A  newe  boke  of  Presidentes  f.  xciib;  for  this  book  see  vol.  v  388-389;  the 
Council's  interference  in  these  cases  was  dictated  by  much  the  same  considerations 
as  those  which  dictated  its  interference  with  loans  at  usurious  interest 


234  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

them.1  Sometimes  it  directed  a  creditor  to  give  his  debtor  time 
till  certain  profits  expected  from  a  voyage  should  be  realized.'2 
Sometimes  it  appointed  commissions  to  enquire  into  the  cases  of 
persons  imprisoned  for  debt ; 3  and  though  the  legality  of  the 
powers  exercised  by  these  commissions  was  very  doubtful,4  the 
commissioners  exerted  pressure  of  an  indirect  but  effectual  kind 
upon  creditors  who  would  not  come  into  the  arrangements  which 
they  suggested.5  This  jurisdiction  was  exercised  throughout  the 
earlier  half  of  the  seventeenth  century.6  On  one  occasion,  in  1637, 
the  Council  stated  that  they  did  not  think  it  reasonable  that  a 
threat  of  bankruptcy  proceedings  should  be  used  to  "strengthen 
the  wilfulness  of  a  few  against  the  general  and  charitable  consent 
of  the  greatest  number  of  the  creditors  "  ;  and  the  Lord  Keeper 
said  that  debtors  who  feared  to  pay,  lest  they  might  be  made  to 
pay  again  by  a  commission  of  bankruptcy,  might  lay  aside  that 
fear,  as  he  should  refuse  to  issue  any  such  commission.  All  the 
debtors  who  refused  to  pay,  and  all  the  creditors  who  refused  to 
agree,  were  ordered  to  attend  the  Council  and  show  their  reasons.7 

(ii)  The  enactments  of  the  Legislature. 

During  the  last  half  of  the  seventeenth  century  the  Council 
ceased  to  exercise  this  jurisdiction,  and  the  Legislature  soon  found 
it  necessary  to  interfere  to  relieve  the  harshness  of  the  law.  Two 
petitions  of  distressed  prisoners  were  presented  to  the  House  of 
Lords  in  1660,8  and  in  1662  and  1664-1665  bills  for  their  relief 
were  considered  by  the  House.9     But  it  was  not  till  1 670-1 671  10 

1  Dasent  viii  128  (1573) ;  ix  212-213  (1576) ;  xiii  112  (1581) ;  xv  16,  27  (1587) ;  xix 
98,  152  (1590). 

2  Ibid  ix  5,  154,  174(1575-1576) — orders  to  creditors  not  to  molest  a  distressed  mer- 
chant till  he  got  in  money  due  to  him  in  France;  ibid  xii  7  (1580) — it  even  relieved 
a  merchant's  necessities  by  giving  him  a  licence  to  export  grain. 

:J  Ibid  xiii  175  (1581). 

4  Vol.  iv  70  ;  vol.  v  432-433  ;  Dasent  xv  99  (1587) — their  doings  had  given  rise  to 
proceedings  under  the  statute  of  Praemunire  ;  ibid  xviii  109  (1589) — a  complaint  that 
the  working  of  the  commission  is  hindered  by  actions  at  law. 

8  Dasent  xxii  384  (1592) — a  letter  of  advice  to  the  commissioners  as  to  their  dealings 
with  creditors  who  refused  to  accept  reasonable  terms  ;  apparently  the  commissioners 
were  to  warn  the  recalcitrants  that  if  they  persisted,  and  afterwards  themselves  got 
into  difficulties,  they  must  not  look  for  any  favour  from  the  Council ;  cp.  ibid  xviii 
433-434  (1589-1590) — recalcitrant  creditors  summoned  to  appear  before  the  Council ; 
Malynes,  op.  cit.  157,  advocated  the  renewal  of  the  commissions  for  the  relief  of 
distressed  prisoners. 

6  See  Acts  of  the  Privy  Council  (1613-1614)  102-103,  169-170,  204,  472,  522-523. 

7S.P.  Dom.  1636-1637,  51,  cccxliii  47,  48;  cp.  ibid  1,  cccxvii  1 ;  for  a  similar  case 
see  ibid  1637,  239,  ccclxii  37  ;  it  appears  from  these  cases  that  the  crown  was  in  the 
habit  of  issuing  protections  in  order  to  facilitate  such  compositions ;  for  an  earlier 
petition  see  ibid  1633 -1634,  3°7i  ccn  5%- 

8  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  7th  Rep.  App.  113,  141 — in  the  latter  petition  it  was  truly  said 
that  the  prisons  were  "sanctuaries  for  the  rich  and  able  debtors,  and  murdering  dens 
of  cruelty  to  poor  men  and  women." 

9  Ibid  164,  181. 

10  For  a  petition  of  these  prisoners  in  1670  see  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  8th  Rep.  App.  152. 


BANKRUPTCY  235 

that  anything  was  done.  By  an  Act  passed  in  that  year '  it  was 
provided  that  a  justice  of  the  peace  could  cause  any  prisoner  for 
debt  to  be  brought  before  him  ;  and  that  if  the  prisoner  swore 
that  he  had  no  estate  above  the  value  of  £10,  and  that  he  had  not 
conveyed  away  his  estate  to  defraud  his  creditors,  a  certificate 
should  be  given  to  the  prisoner,  and  notice  should  be  given  to  the 
creditor  to  appear  at  the  next  quarter  sessions.2  If  the  prisoner's 
oath  could  not  there  be  disproved  he  was  to  be  discharged.3  If, 
however,  the  creditor  insisted  on  keeping  him  in  prison,  he  must 
pay  a  weekly  sum  for  his  maintenance.4  Notwithstanding  the 
discharge  of  the  prisoner,  judgments  were  to  stand  good,  and  new 
executions  against  the  prisoner's  property  could  be  sued  out.0 
Enquiries  were  to  be  made  into  the  administration  of  funds  given 
for  the  relief  of  poor  prisoners ; 6  felons  and  prisoners  for  debt 
were  not  to  be  lodged  together ; :  and  certain  other  abuses 
committed  by  gaolers  or  their  officers  were  prohibited.8  In  1678  9 
this  Act  was  extended  to  persons  imprisoned  on  mesne  process.10 
Prisoners  kept  in  prison  with  a  weekly  allowance  from  their 
creditors  were  to  be  released,  if  no  estate  belonging  to  them  could 
be  discovered  within  three  months.11  Debtors  who  were  labourers 
could  be  removed  to  the  workhouse,  and  could  demand  their 
release  after  two  years.12  The  Act  was  not  to  apply  to  debtors 
who  had  not  been  in  prison  for  six  months,13  or  who  owed  more 
than  ^500,u  or  to  aliens  in  respect  of  debts  contracted  abroad  ; la 
and  a  discharge  was  made  conditional  on  a  full  disclosure  by  a 
debtor  of  his  effects,  and  of  the  debts  owing  to  him.16  In  1690  an 
attempt  was  made  to  prevent  debtors  from  using  the  Acts  to 
defraud  their  creditors,  by  causing  themselves  to  be  imprisoned  in 
collusive  actions ; 17  and  further  amendments  of  the  law  were  made 
in  1694  18  and  1695-1696.19  It  was  provided  by  the  latter  of  these 
two  Acts  that  the  Acts  should  not  apply  to  debtors  taken  in 
execution  for  the  non-payment  of  fines  imposed  for  offences,20  to 
debtors  to  the  king,21  or  to  those  owing  damages  for  wrongs  which 
were  felonious.22 

I  22,  23  Charles  II.  c.  20.  3  §  1.  3  Ibid.  4  §  2. 

5  §  4 ;  see  also  30  Charles  II.  c.  4  §  5 ;  it  was  provided  by  §  8  of  the  last  named 
Act  that  the  discharge  of  the  prisoner  did  not  release  a  surety. 
•22,  23  Charles  II.  c.  20  §  9.  7  §  11. 

8  §§  6-8.  »  30  Charles  II.  c.  4.  10  §  1. 

II  §  3 ;  this  section  provided  that  the  allowance  was  to  be  paid,  not  to  the  gaoler, 
but  to  the  prisoner,  and  §  11  provided  that  the  weekly  allowance  need  not  be  made  if  a 
relation  liable  to  maintain  the  prisoner  was  able  to  do  so. 

12  §§12,  13.  "§9. 

14  §  10 ;  reduced  to  £100  by  7,  8  William  III.  c.  12  §  9. 

19  §  18.  16§  19.  "2  William  and  Mary  Sess.  2  c.  15. 

18  5,  6  William  and  Mary  c  8.  197,  8  William  III.  c.  12. 

80  §8.  21§9. 

22  §  15 ;  to  encourage  recruiting  it  was  provided  by  §  14  that  no  one  under  forty 
was  to  get  his  discharge  unless  he  either  enlisted  or  procured  some  one  else  to  enlist. 


236  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

The  number  of  these  Acts  leads  us  to  think  that  they  were 
not  very  effectual,  either  to  procure  the  release  of  prisoners,  or  to 
put  a  stop  to  the  malpractices  of  gaolers  or  their  officers.  The 
justices  of  the  peace  were  not  well  fitted  to  do  the  duties  imposed 
on  them.  Gaolers  and  officials  were  more  iikely  to  side  with  rich 
creditors  than  poor  debtors  ; l  and  the  same  might  probably  be 
said  of  many  of  the  justices.  For  these  reasons  these  Acts  were 
probably  less  effective  than  the  measures  adopted  by  the  Council 
in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries. 

(2)  The  measures  taken  against  dishonest  debtors. 

(i)  The  activities  of  the  Council. 

During  the  earlier  part  of  this  period  the  Council  interfered  in 
the  case  of  the  fraudulent  bankrupt,  either  to  set  the  law  in  motion,2 
or  to  give  directions  in  specific  cases.3  But  in  this  class  of  case 
their  efforts  were  seconded,  and  to  a  large  extent  superseded,  by 
the  Legislature,  at  a  much  earlier  period  than  in  the  case  of  the 
unfortunate  debtor. 

(ii)  The  enactments  of  the  Legislature. 

It  is  in  the  enactments  of  the  Legislature,  passed  to  deal  with 
the  dishonest  debtor,  that  we  must  look  for  the  origins  of  the  law 
of  bankruptcy.  All  of  the  bankruptcy  Acts  passed  in  this  period 
were  Acts  passed  with  this  object.  All  were  directed  against 
fraudulent  bankrupts,  and  aimed,  not  at  relieving  the  bankrupt, 
but  at  getting  his  property  for  the  benefit  of  his  creditors. 

The  first  of  these  Acts  was  passed  in  1 542-1 543. 4  It  recites 
that  "  divers  and  sundry  persons,  craftily  obtaining  into  their  hands 
great  substance  of  other  men's  goods,  do  suddenly  flee  to  parts 
unknown,  or  keep  their  houses,  not  minding  to  pay  or  restore  to 
any  their  .creditors,  their  debts  and  duties  "  ;  and  it  empowers  the 
Lord  Chancellor  and  certain  other  officials,  and  the  two  chief 
justices,  to  seize  the  property  and  imprison  the  persons  of  such 
debtors,  and  to  distribute  their  property  among  their  creditors. 
The  debtors  of  these  persons,  and  anyone  suspected  of  having  in 
their  possession  any  of  their  property,  could  be  summoned,  ex- 
amined, and  required  to  make  payment  or  restitution,  they  could 
also  be  required    to  disclose  any  facts  within  their  knowledge. 


1  This  complaint  was  made  in  a  petition  of  the  prisoners  to  the  House  of  Lords  in 
1672-1673,  Hist.  MSS.  Com.  gth  Rep.  App.  26 ;  a  bill  to  improve  the  original  Act  of 
1670-1671  was  read  a  first  time  in  1673-1674,  but  failed  to  pass,  ibid  37;  and  another 
bill  of  the  same  kind  failed  to  pass  in  1690,  ibid  13th  Rep.  App.  Pt.  V.  161  no.  322. 

2Dasent  v  344  (1556);  vii  47  (1558-1559)  5  x  *5,  37  (1577-1578);  xii  34*-342 
(1580-1581);  xiv  78,  95,  131,  192  (1586-15S7). 

3  Ibid  x  66,  391  (1577-1578) ;  xiii  310-311  (1581-1582) — an  order  that  a  creditor  who 
was  an  ambassador  should  be  paid  in  full. 

434>  35  Henry  VIII.  c.  4;  Coke,  Fourth  Instit.  277,  278;  vol  i  470. 


BANKRUPTCY  237 

Creditors  who  got  undue  preference  from  absconding  debtors  could 
be  punished ;  and  collusive  recoveries  got  aga'nst  these  debtors 
could  be  set  aside.  These  proceedings  could  be  taken  against 
debtors  who  withdrew  themselves  out  of  the  kingdom,  or  who  kept 
their  houses  or  otherwise  concealed  themselves,  in  order  to  avoid 
the  payment  of  their  debts. 

This  statute  was  replaced  in  1 571  *  by  a  much  more  compre- 
hensive statute,  which  was  amended  and  enlarged  by  statutes  of 
16042  and  1623.3  These  three  statutes  contain  the  bankruptcy 
law  of  this  period. 

These  statutes  (a)  define  the  persons  who  can  become  bank- 
rupts ;  (b)  catalogue  the  various  possible  acts  of  bankruptcy ;  (c) 
vest  the  jurisdiction  in  bankruptcy  in  commissioners  appointed  by 
the  Lord  Chancellor  ;  (d)  assign  various  powers  to  the  commis- 
sioners to  enable  them  to  collect  and  distribute  the  assets  of  the 
bankrupt  ;  (e)  define  their  duties  to  the  creditors  and  the  bankrupt ; 
{/)  provide  for  increasing  in  various  ways  the  assets  available  for 
distribution  among  the  creditors;  and  (g)  define  the  effect  of 
bankruptcy  on  the  liability  of  the  bankrupt  Let  us  glance  shortly 
at  these  seven  points. 

(a)  The  persons  who  can  become  bankrupts. — All  the  Acts  con- 
fine the  class  of  persons  who  can  become  bankrupts  to  traders.4 
Under  the  two  earlier  Acts  they  must  also  be  British  subjects  ;  but 
the  act  of  1623  provided  that  aliens  could  be  made  bankrupts, 
and  that  they  could  prove  as  creditors.5  It  was  decided  in  1700 
that  an  infant  could  not  be  made  a  bankrupt  because  the  debts  of 
an  infant  are  voidable ;  and  "no  man  can  be  a  bankrupt  for  debts 
which  he  is  not  obliged  to  pay."  6 

(b)  The  acts  of  bankruptcy. — The  statute  of  1571  declared  the 
following  acts,  if  done  with  the  intention  of  defrauding  or  hinder- 
ing creditors,  to  be  acts  of  bankruptcy  : — departure  from  the  realm  ; 
keeping  house  or  otherwise  absenting  oneself ;  taking  sanctuary  ; 
suffering  oneself  to  be  arrested  for  debt ;    suffering  oneself  to  be 

1 13  Elizabeth  c.  7.  2  1  James  I.  c  15.  *2i  James  I.  c.  19 

4Cp.  Monro,  Acta  Cancellaria  286;  it  was  enacted  by  14  Charles  II.  c.  24  that  the 
mere  fact  that  a  person  was  a  shareholder  in  the  East  India,  African,  and  Fishery 
companies  should  not  make  him  a  trader  within  the  meaning  of  the  bankruptcy  Acts, 
and  a  decision  to  the  contrary  was  declared  to  be  contrary  to  law.  This  privilege  was 
extended  to  holders  of  stock  in  the  Bank  of  England  by  8,  9  William  III.  c.  20  §  47  ; 
apparently  neither  farmers  nor  inn-keepers  were  traders  within  the  meaning  of  the  Acts, 
Meggot  v.  Mills  (169S)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  287. 

5  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  15  ;  apparently,  before  this  statute,  where  an  English  debtor 
abroad  attempted  to  evade  his  foreign  creditors  by  transferring  his  property  and  coming 
to  England,  the  court  of  Chancery  intervened  to  help  the  foreign  creditors,  Sere  and 
Eland  v.  Colley  (1610-1611)  Tothill  68-69;  and  CP-  Monro,  Acta  Cancellaria  169  n ; 
the  fact  that  the  bankrupt  and  the  creditor  were  out  of  England  was  immaterial,  Wild 
v.  Middleton  (1632)  Tothill  75. 

6  Rex  v.  Cole  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  443. 


238  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

outlawed  or  imprisoned ;  or  departing  from  one's  house.1  The 
statute  of  1604  repeated  this  list  with  some  small  verbal  modifica- 
tions, and  required  the  acts  to  be  done  with  the  intention  of  hinder- 
ing or  delaying  creditors.  It  added  the  two  following  acts  if  done 
with  a  like  intent — suffering  one's  goods  and  chattels  to  be  attached, 
and  making  a  fraudulent  conveyance  of  one's  lands  or  goods.  It 
further  added  the  two  following  acts,  whether  this  intent  was  present 
or  not — suffering  oneself  to  be  arrested  for  debt  and  lying  in  prison 
six  months,2  and  non-appearance  when  summoned  by  the  commis- 
sioners.3 The  statute  of  1623  4  added  the  following :  procuring 
protections ;  presenting  a  petition  against  one's  creditors  to  force 
them  to  take  less  than  their  original  debts,  or  to  get  a  longer  time 
of  payment ;  being  indebted  for  £100  or  more  and  not  paying  the 
debt  within  six  months  after  arrest,  or  the  suing  out  of  the  original 
writ ;  being  arrested  for  such  a  debt  and  escaping,  or  getting  out 
by  giving  common  bail.5 

(c)  The  jurisdiction  in  bankruptcy. — This  was  vested  in  "wise 
honest  and  discreet  persons  "  commissioned  by  the  Lord  Chancel- 
lor.6 Malynes  tells  us  that  they  were  generally  counsellors  at  law 
joined  with  some  citizens  or  merchants ;  and  that  they  generally 
appointed  one  or  two  of  the  creditors  to  be  the  treasurers  of  the 
fund  to  be  distributed.7  They  were  entitled  to  be  paid  for  their 
trouble  in  executing  the  commission  ; 8  and,  in  case  of  unfair  deal- 
ing, they  were  subject  to  the  control  of  the  court  of  Chancery.9 

(d)  The  powers  of  the  commissioners. — They  could  take  the  body 
of  the  bankrupt,  and  could  take  and  dispose  of  his  property  for  the 
benefit  of  his  creditors.10  They  could  examine  the  bankrupt  or  his 
wife  upon  oath.11  They  could  imprison  him  if  he  refused  to  answer 
their  questions  as  to  his  property ; 12  and  he  could  be  punished  by 
the  pillory  and  cutting  off  of  an  ear  if  he  committed  perjury.13 

1 13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  1.  2  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  2. 

3  Ibid  §  6.  42i  James  I.  c.  19  §  2. 

5  For  common  bail  see  vol.  i  220.  e  13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  2. 

7  Op.  cit.  158 — "  The  Commissioners  appointed  by  the  Lord  Chancellor  under  the 
great  Seal,  to  execute  this  commission  of  the  Statute  of  Bankrupts,  must  be  Counsellors 
at  the  law,  joyned  with  some  citizens  or  merchants,  which  are  to  seise  of  the  party 
(which  by  the  said  commission  is  proved  to  be  a  bankrupt)  all  goods,  debts,  chattels, 
and  moveables  into  their  hands,  and  to  appoint  one  or  two  of  the  creditors  to  be  Trea- 
surers of  the  same,  which  is  afterwards  to  be  distributed  by  the  said  Commissioners, 
unto  all  such  as  they  shall  find  and  admit  to  be  right  Creditors  to  the  party  (and  with 
his  privity  and  consent)  upon  such  specialities,  books,  or  accounts,  as  they  shall  pro- 
duce, and  be  made  apparent  unto  them." 

8  Hawarde,  Les  Reports,  etc.,  342-343,  tells  us  that  in  1607  an  action  was  brought 
against  three  commissioners  (two  being  members  of  Gray's  Inn  and  one  an  attorney) 
for  taking  money  (£22) ;  the  action  was  dismissed,  "  And  the  Lo.  Chancellor  sayde  he 
was  sorrye  they  took  no  more  (for  with  a  Lawyer  Cessans  Lucrum  damnum  est)  and 
yf  Commissioners  shoulde  not  have  rewarde  for  their  travell  and  Charges  no  Commis- 
sion woulde  be  executed." 

9  Wood  v.  Hayes  (1606-1607)  Tothill  62.  10  13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  2. 
11 1  James  I.  c.  15  §  7  ;  21  James  I,  c.  19  §  6. 

12  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  8.  i=»  Ibid  §  9. 


BANKRUPTCY  239 

They  could  summon  before  them  and  examine  upon  oath  debtors 
of  the  bankrupt,  or  anyone  suspected  of  being  in  possession  of  any 
part  of  the  bankrupt's  property.  In  case  of  a  refusal  to  answer 
they  could  commit  to  prison.1  Fraudulent  concealment  by  a 
bankrupt  of  his  property  to  the  value  of  ^"20  was  punishable  by 
the  pillory  and  loss  of  an  ear.2  They  could  break  open  the  doors 
of  the  bankrupt's  house  in  the  execution  of  their  commission.3 
They  could  assign  to  a  creditor  any  debt  due  to  a  bankrupt,  and 
the  creditor  could  sue  for  and  recover  it  in  his  own  name.4  They 
could  make  a  grant  of  the  bankrupt's  entailed  lands  by  deed  en- 
rolled, which  would  hold  good  as  against  all  persons  whose  inter- 
ests the  bankrupt  might  have  barred  by  suffering  a  recovery ; 5  and 
they  could  redeem  any  estates  conveyed  upon  condition  by  the 
bankrupt,  which  might  have  been  redeemed  by  him.6  Evasion  of 
the  commissioners'  powers,  by  the  pretence  that  the  bankrupt  was 
indebted  to  the  king,  was  prevented  by  giving  the  commissioners 
power  to  enquire  into  the  real  facts.7  Their  powers  were  not  de- 
termined by  the  death  of  the  bankrupt.8 

(e)  The  duties  of  the  commissioners  to  the  creditors  and  the 
bankrupt. — The  estate  must  be  rateably  divided  among  the  credi- 
tors.9 This  rule  of  equal  division  was  applied,  even  though  a 
creditor  had  a  judgment,  statute,  recognizance,  specialty,  attach- 
ment, or  other  security.10  Until  distribution  was  made  among  the 
creditors,  other  creditors  could  come  in  and  claim  a  dividend,  on 
condition  of  contributing  rateably  to  the  cost  of  the  commission  ; 
but  if  they  did  not  come  in  within  four  months  the  commissioners 
might  distribute.11  The  commissioners  must,  if  required,  account 
to  the  bankrupt  for  the  manner  in  which  they  had  employed  his 
property,  and  pay  him  any  surplus  after  the  discharge  of  all  his 
debts.12 

(/")  Assets  available  for  distribution. — All  these  statutes  contain 
provisions  for  setting  aside  certain  dispositions  by  the  bankrupt  of 
his  property,  in  order  to  increase  the  amount  available  for  the 
creditors.  The  statute  of  1571  provided  that  after-acquired  pro- 
perty of  the  bankrupt  was  to  be  available  for  the  creditors ;  but 
not  property  bona   fide   conveyed    to   other  persons   before  the 

1 13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §§  5,  6  ;  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  10 ;  see  Bracy's  Case  (1697)  1  Ld. 
Raym.  99. 

2  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  7.  3  Ibid  §  8  ;  Anon.  (1682)  2  Shower  K.B.  247. 

4  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  13. 

5  21  James  I.  c.  ig  §  12  ;  this  is  a  curious  anticipation  of  the  plan  adopted  by  the 
Fines  and  Recoveries  Act  of  1833. 

«  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  13.  7  Ibid  §  10. 

8  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  17 ;  but  it  was  determined  by  the  death  of  the  king  till 
5  George  II.  c.  30  §  44. 

9  13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  2.  >»  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  9. 

11  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  4.  » 13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  4  ;  1  James  I.  c-  15  §  15. 


240  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

bankruptcy.1  The  statute  of  1604  made  a  more  stringent  pro- 
vision. It  enacted  that  all  conveyances  made  by  a  bankrupt  of  his 
property  before  bankruptcy,  unless  made  in  consideration  of  marriage 
or  for  value,  could  be  treated  as  void  ; 2  but,  under  the  statute  of  1623, 
if  a  conveyance  was  made  after  an  act  of  bankruptcy  committed, 
no  purchaser  for  good  and  valuable  consideration  could  be  im- 
peached, unless  the  commission  were  sued  out  within  five  years  of 
the  act  of  bankruptcy.3  These  provisions  aimed  at  swelling  the 
assets  by  getting  back  property  which  had  formerly  belonged  to 
the  bankrupt.  The  statute  of  1623  aimed  also  at  swelling  the 
assets  by  taking  the  property  of  other  persons  in  the  possession  of 
the  bankrupt.  With  that  object  it  introduced  the  reputed  owner- 
ship rule.  Goods  in  the  possession,  order,  and  disposition  of  the 
bankrupt,  by  the  consent  of  the  true  owner,  could  be  disposed  of 
for  the  benefit  of  the  creditors.4 

(g)  The  effect  of  bankruptcy  on  the  liability  of  the  bankrupt. — 
None  of  these  statutes  discharged  the  bankrupt  from  his  liabilities, 
except  to  the  extent  to  which  the  creditors  had  been  paid.  The 
statute  of  1 57 1  specially  provided  that  all  creditors  should  con- 
tinue to  have  all  the  remedies  which  they  then  possessed  in 
respect  of  any  part  of  the  debt  which  remained  unrealized.5 

The  policy  of  these  statutes  was  well  described  by  Coke  in 
The  Case  of  Bankrupts?  "  The  intent  .  .  .  was  to  relieve  the 
creditors  of  the  bankrupt  equally,  and  that  there  should  be  an 
equal  and  rateable  proportion  observed  in  the  distribution  of  the 
bankrupt's  goods  amongst  the  creditors,  having  regard  to  the 
quantity  of  their  several  debts."  Therefore,  although  the  property 
was  not  taken  from  the  bankrupt  till  the  commissioners  had  made 
an  assignment,7  he  could  not  dispose  of  his  property  after  he  had 
become  bankrupt 8 — otherwise  he  might  have  made  a  fraudulent 
preference  and  so  have  defeated  the  policy  of  the  statutes.  When 
an  assignment  had  been  made,  the  title  of  the  creditor  related 
back  to  the  bankruptcy,  so  as  to  avoid  all  intermediate  dealings 
with  it.9 

The  date  of  the  bankruptcy  was  the  committing  of  an  act  of 
bankruptcy ;  and  it  was  the  duty  of  the  commissioners  to  deter- 
mine whether  such  an  act  had  been  committed.  Necessarily  the 
courts  of  law  reserved  power  to  review  this  decision.  It  was  said, 
in  Bonhams  Case,  that  the  court  had  decided  that  the  finding  of 

1 13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §§  11,  12.  2  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  5. 

3  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  14. 

4  21  James  I.  c.  19  §  11 ;  cp.  Meggot  v.  Mills  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  286. 

6  13  Elizabeth  c.  7  §  10.  « (1584)  2  Co.  Rep.  at  p,  25b. 

7  Carey  v.  Crisp  (1689)  1  Salk.  108. 

*The  Case  of  Bankrupts  (1584)  2  Co.  Rep.  at  pp.  25a,  26b. 
9  Kiggil  v.  Player  (1709)  1  Salk.  in. 


BANKRUPTCY  241 

the  commissioners  that  a  man  was  a  bankrupt,  was  traversable  in 
an  action  of  false  imprisonment.1  Similarly,  on  a  writ  of  habeas 
corpus,  the  legality  of  a  commitment  by  the  commissioners  could 
be  questioned.2  It  was  only  a  trader  who  could  be  made  bank- 
rupt ;  and  the  question  whether  a  person  was  a  trader  within  the 
meaning  of  the  bankruptcy  Acts  was  often  before  the  courts, 
generally  on  a  reference  from  the  Chancellor.3  Sometimes  this 
question  was  determined  by  the  more  indirect  manner  of  an 
action  for  slander ;  for  the  question  whether  it  was  an  actionable 
slander  to  call  a  man  bankrupt  depended  upon  whether  he  was  a 
trader  within  the  meaning  of  the  Acts.4 

It  was  only  on  the  petition  of  the  creditors  that  a  commission 
could  issue ; 5  and,  on  such  a  petition,  the  Chancellor  held  that  its 
issue  was  a  matter  of  right.8  The  commissioners  would  then 
decide  whether  an  act  of  bankruptcy  had  been  committed,  or 
whether  a  debt  was  proved,  subject  to  an  appeal  to  the  Lord 
Chancellor,  or  a  reference  to  the  judges.7 

The  common  law  decisions  upon  the  interpretation  of  the 
Acts  turn,  for  the  most  part,  merely  on  the  construction  of 
particular  sections.8  They  do  not  add  very  much  to  the  statute 
law.  For  these  additions  we  must  look  rather  to  the  decisions  of 
the  Chancellor.  We  have  seen  that  the  court  of  Chancery  would 
interfere  in  case  of  unfair  dealing ; 9  and  towards  the  end  of  this 
period  it  began  to  deal  with  other  questions  as  to  bankruptcy 
administration.10  One  class  of  these  cases  turns  upon  the  question 
whether  certain  equitable  interests  could  be  deemed  to  be  assets. 
Thus  it  was  held  that  property  settled  for  the  benefit  of  the  wife 
and  children  of  the  bankrupt  could  not  be  taken,11  or  even  an 
annuity  settled  by  a  father  on  his  soa12  It  was  even  doubted  for 
some  time  whether  an  equity  of  redemption  was  an  asset  assignable 


1  (1609)  8  Co.  Rep.  at  p.  121a,  "  Because  the  party  grieved  has  no  other  remedy, 
if  the  commissioners  do  not  pursue  the  Act  and  their  commission,  he  shall  traverse 
that  he  was  not  a  bankrupt,  although  the  commissioners  affirm  him  to  be  one :  as 
this  term  it  was  resolved  in  this  Court,  in  trespass  between  Ctttt  and  Delabarre,  where 
the  issue  was,  whether  William  Cheyney  was  a  bankrupt  or  not,  who  was  found  by 
the  commissioners  to  be  a  bankrupt." 

2  Bracey  v.  Harris  (1097)  5  Mod.  3og. 

s  Monro,  Acta  Cancellaria  286  ;  Bacon's  Ab.  tit.  Bankrupt  A,  "  the  usual  method 
when  Bankruptcy  is  denied,  is  for  my  Lord  Chancellor  to  order  it  to  be  tried  in  a 
Common-Law  Court,  on  an  Issue,  Bankrupt,  or  not  "  ;  see  that  title,  and  above  237 
n.  4,  for  various  cases ;  the  rule  that  only  a  trader  could  be  made  bankrupt  was  the 
same  in  French  law,  Brissaud,  op.  cit.  ii  1465. 

4  See  e.g.  Squire  v.  Johns  (1621)  Cro.  Jac.  585. 

s  Alderman  Backwell's  Case  (1687)  2  Cases  in  Chancery  at  p.  191. 

6  S.C.  (1683)  1  Vern.  152.  7  Above  n.  3  ;  Anon.  (1676)  1  Chy.  Cas.  275. 

8  See  Bacon's  Ab.  tit.  Bankrupt 

9  Above  238.  10  Vol.  i  470. 

11  Vandenanker  v.  Desbrough  (i68g)  2  Vern.  96. 

12  Moyses  v.  Little  (1690)  2  Vern.  194. 
VOL.  VIII.— 16 


242  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

by  the  commissioners.1  Another  class  of  cases  turns  upon  the 
modes  of  distribution  adopted  by  the  commissioners;2  another 
upon  the  rights  of  different  classes  of  creditors ; 3  and  another 
upon  the  validity  of  an  assignment  made  before  bankruptcy.4 
But  perhaps  the  most  interesting  questions  were  those  which  arose 
in  the  case  of  the  bankruptcy  of  a  partnership,  and  in  the  case  of 
the  bankruptcy  of  a  purchaser  of  land  or  goods.  In  the  manner 
in  which  the  court  of  Chancery  dealt  with  both  these  cases  we  can 
trace  new  and  important  principles  of  law. 

In  the  partnership  cases  we  see  the  beginning  of  the  modern 
rule 5  that  the  joint  estate  is  primarily  liable  to  the  joint  debts,  and 
the  separate  estate  to  the  separate  debts.  In  the  earliest  of  these 
cases,  in  1682,0  two  partners  had  agreed  that  debts  owing  on  the 
joint  account  should  be  paid  out  of  the  joint  stock,  and  that  the 
joint  stock  should  not  be  charged  with  the  separate  debts.  But, 
on  the  petition  of  a  separate  creditor,  the  court  decreed  that  the 
joint  stock  and  joint  debts  should  be  divided  into  moieties ;  that 
each  moiety  of  the  stock  should  be  charged  with  a  moiety  of  the 
joint  debts  ;  and  that  which  was  over  must  be  applied  to  pay  the 
separate  debts  of  the  partners.  If  the  joint  stock  was  not  enough 
to  pay  all  the  joint  debts,  and  either  partner  paid  more  than  a 
moiety,  he  could  come  in  as  a  creditor  for  the  amount  overpaid 
by  him  ;  and  presumably  his  separate  creditors  would  get  paid  out 
01  any  dividend  he  so  got.  In  subsequent  proceedings  in  the  same 
case,  Lord  North  seemed  to  think  that  the  agreement  of  the 
partners  that  the  joint  debts  should  be  paid  out  of  the  joint  stock 
was  ineffectual,  as  it  could  not  bind  their  creditors.  But  the 
reporter  adds  a  quaere  whether  the  separate  creditors  could  have 
any  better  title  than  the  partners  under  whom  they  claimed.7 
Whether  or  not  the  primary  liability  of  the  joint  stock  to  the  joint 
creditors,  and  the  primary  liability  of  the  separate  estate  to  the 
separate  creditors,  was  based  on  this  ground  is  not  clear ;  but  it  is 
clear  that  in  171  5  we  get  in  substance  the  modern  rule.8  A  com- 
mission of  bankruptcy  having  issued  against  two  partners,  the 
separate  creditors  applied  to  be  let  in  to  prove  their  separate 
debts  against  their  separate  estates.  They  were  allowed  to  do  so  ; 
and  it  was  directed  "  that  as  the  joint  or  partnership  estate  was  in 

1  Vandenanker  v.  Desbrough  (1689)  2  Vern.  at  p.  97. 

2  Hitchcock  v.  Sedgwick  (1690)  2  Vern.  at  p.  162  ;  in  1693-1694  a  bill  for  "  the 
more  equal  distribution  of  bankrupts'  estates  "  was  thrown  out  by  the  House  of  Lords, 
Luttrell  s  Diary  iii  285. 

3  2  Vern.  at  p.  157;  Craven  v.  Knight  (1682)  2  Rep.  in  Ch.  226. 

4  Meechett  v.  Bradshaw  (1633-1634)  Nelson  22. 

5  Pollock,  Digest  of  the  Law  of  Partnership  (nth  ed.)  159  seqq. 

6  Craven  v.  Knight  (1682)  2  Rep.  in  Ch.  226,  229  ;  1  Eq.  Cas.  Ab.  55. 

7  Craven  v.  Widdows  (1683)  2  Cases  in  Ch.  i3g. 

8  Ex  pte.  Crowder  2  Vern.  706. 


BANKRUPTCY  243 

the  first  place  to  be  applied  to  pay  the  joint  or  partnership  debts ; 
so  in  like  manner  the  separate  estate  should  be  in  the  first  place 
to  pay  all  the  separate  debts ;  and  as  separate  creditors  are  not  to 
be  let  in  upon  the  joint  estate  until  all  the  joint  debts  are  first 
paid ;  so  likewise  the  creditors  to  the  partnership  shall  not  come 
in  for  any  deficiency  of  the  joint  estate,  upon  the  separate  estate, 
until  the  separate  debts  are  first  paid."  At  an  earlier  date  it  had 
been  settled  that  if  a  partner  embezzled  the  partnership  property 
and  became  a  bankrupt,  the  partners  could,  in  priority  to  the 
separate  creditors,  get  from  his  share  of  the  partnership  assets  the 
amount  which  he  had  embezzled.1  This  seems  to  be  the  origin  of 
one  of  the  exceptions  to  the  general  rule ; 2  but  as  yet  very  little 
has  been  done  to  differentiate  the  various  exceptions  to  this  rule, 
and  to  ascertain  their  scope  and  application. 

It  was  laid  down  in  1 684  that  where  a  bankrupt,  having 
bought  land,  had  not  paid  all  the  purchase  money,  the  vendor 
need  not  come  in  as  a  creditor  for  the  rest  of  the  money  ;  but  that 
the  land  should  be  charged  with  the  balance  due.3  In  1690  it 
was  laid  down  that,  when  goods  had  been  consigned  by  unpaid 
vendors  to  purchasers,  who  went  bankrupt  before  the  ship  convey- 
ing them  had  sailed,  then,  although  the  property  had  passed  at 
law,  the  vendor  could  retake  the  goods.  "  If  they  by  any  means 
get  these  goods  again  into  their  hands,  or  prevent  their  coming 
into  the  hands  of  the  bankrupts,  it  was  but  lawful  for  them  so  to  do, 
and  very  allowable  in  equity."  4  It  is  clear  that  in  these  two 
cases  we  have  the  origins  of  two  exceptional  rules  in  the  law  of 
bankruptcy — the  rule  which  gives  the  vendor  of  real  estate  an 
equitable  lien  and  so  makes  him  a  secured  creditor,  and  the  rule 
that  an  unpaid  vendor  of  goods  can  stop  in  transitu  as  against  a 
bankrupt  purchaser. 

The  bankruptcy  law  established  by  these  statutes  suffered  from 
two  great  defects.  In  the  first  place,  it  made  no  sort  of  differentia- 
tion between  the  unfortunate,  and  the  dishonest  or  reckless  bankrupt. 
The  governing  idea  of  the  statutes  was  that  the  bankrupt  is  an 
offender ;  and  the  fact  that  they  provided  for  no  discharge  of  the 
bankrupt  from  his  liabilities,  as  the  result  of  bankruptcy  proceed- 
ings, is  characteristic  of  this  governing  idea.  The  result  was  that 
the  rogue  often  escaped  while  "  plain  dealing  men  were  laid  hold 
of."  5  In  the  second  place,  there  is  some  reason  to  think  that  the 
commissioners  who  exercised  this  jurisdiction  were  not  always 
very  competent.     It  was  said  in  Alderman  Backwell's  Case  that 

1  Richardson  v.  Godwin  (1693)  2  Vern.  293.  s  Pollock,  op.  tit.  172. 

s  Chapman  v.  Turner  (1684)  1  Vern.  267,  268 — '« in  this  case  there  is  a  natural 
equity  that  the  land  should  stand  charged  with  so  much  of  the  purchase  money  as  was 
not  paid ;  and  that  without  any  special  agreement  for  that  purpose." 

*  Wiseman  v.  Vandeputt  (1690)  2  Vern.  203.  s  Malynes,  op.  cit.  157. 


244  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  fact  that  the  commissioners  were  liable  to  be  sued,  if  they  had 
acted  wrongly,  caused  the  most  sufficient  persons  to  avoid  serving  ; 1 
and  there  is  evidence  that  the  administration  of  the  law  was  in 
consequence  both  expensive  and  dilatory.2  For  both  these  reasons 
it  is  clear  that  the  application  of  a  measure  of  discriminating  equity 
was  needed.  It  is  therefore  not  surprising  that,  at  the  latter  part 
of  this  period,  the  Chancellor  began  to  interfere  more  actively  with 
the  administration  of  the  law  by  the  commissioners  ; 3  that  several 
proposals  for  a  reform  of  the  law  were  made ; 4  and  that  early  in 
the  following  period  it  was  materially  modified.  Even  with  these 
modifications,  both  the  law  itself  and  its  administration  continued 
to  be  one  of  the  most  unsatisfactory  branches  of  English  law  till 
the  reforms  of  the  nineteenth  century.5  All  these  defects  were 
aggravated  by  the  limited  scope  of  the  bankruptcy  laws,  which, 
as  we  have  seen,  applied  only  to  traders ;  and  by  the  fact  that  no 
person,  whether  or  not  he  came  within  the  scope  of  these  laws, 
could  force  his  creditors  to  assent  to  a  composition. 

That  this  was  so  was  largely  due  to  the  fact  that  the  abolition 
of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Council  in  1641,  had  left  no  machinery 
by  which  an  honest  but  unfortunate  debtor  could  make  an  effectual 
composition  with  his  creditors,  unless  all  the  creditors  agreed.8 
At  one  time,  it  is  true,  the  court  of  Chancery  would,  by  means  of 
a  bill  of  conformity,  compel  a  minority  of  creditors  to  assent  to  a 
composition  of  which  a  majority  had  approved.7  But  this  practice 
gave  rise  to  abuses — such  bills  were  filed  merely  to  delay  pro- 
ceedings at  law.8  It  was  therefore  ordered  by  proclamation  in 
1 62 1  9  that  such  bills  should  be  dismissed  if  the  creditors  did  not 
consent ;  and  it  was  enacted  in  1623  that  the  filing  of  such  a  bill 
should  be  an  act  of  bankruptcy.10  Several  attempts  were  made  at 
the  end  of  this  period  to  pass  Acts  to  facilitate  these  compositions.11 
An  Act  was  passed  in  1696- 1697  ; 12  but  it  was  repealed  in  the 

1  "  It  was  a  mischief  that  the  Act  of  Parliament  had  subjected  the  Commis- 
sioners to  an  action,  so  that  no  sufficient  persons  .  .  .  would  undertake  the  trouble 
of  it,"  1  Vein,  at  p.  154  ;  see  1  James  I.  c.  15  §  16  for  the  procedure  in  these  actions. 

2  S.P.  Dom.  1677-1678  644  ;  ibid  1678  85.  3  Vol.  i  470-471. 
4  A  bill  for  the  better  recovery  of  bankrupt's  estates,  and  for  the  more  equal 

distribution  thereof,  failed  to  pass  the  House  of  Lords  in  1693-1694,  House  of  Lords 
MSS.  i  no.  815  ;  another  bill  ta  effect  a  more  equal  distribution  of  insolvent's  estates 
failed  to  pass  in  1694-1695,  ibid  no.  882. 

6  Vol.  i  471-473.  6  Above  234. 

7  Ramsey  v.  Brabson  (1583-1584)  Choyce  Cases  174  ;  Tothill  25-26  (1613-1614) ; 
ibid  47  (1613  and  1626). 

8Malynes,  op.  cit.  160.  9  Tudor  and  Stuart  Proclamations  i  no.  13 12. 

10 21  James  I.  c.  19  §  2.5;  in  Alderman  Backwells  Case  (1683)  1  Vern.  at  p. 
153  it  was  said  by  the  court  that,  "  Bills  of  Conformity  have  long  since  been  exploded, 
and  there  was  no  such  equity  now  in  the  court." 

11 A  bill  to  facilitate  compositions  with  creditors  was  considered  by  the  House  of 
Commons  in  1679,  S.P.  Dom.  1679-1680  138,  147 ;  Commons  Journals  ix  613 ;  a 
similar  bill  failed  to  pass  the  House  of  Lords  in  1694-1695,  House  of  Lords  MSS.  i 

no.  911' 

"  8,  9  William  III.  c.  18. 


MARITIME  LAW  245 

following  year.1  The  result  was  that,  right  down  to  the  beginning 
of  the  nineteenth  century,  no  means  were  provided  for  enforcing 
a  just  composition  with  creditors  ; 2  and  this  defect  was  aggravated 
by  the  power  which  each  creditor  had  of  oppressing  the  debtor  by 
taking  his  body  in  execution.3  The  resulting  hardship  on  debtors, 
who  were  unable  for  any  reason  to  take  advantage  of  the  bank- 
ruptcy laws,  was  forcibly  pointed  out  by  the  Common  Law  Com- 
missioners in  1831-1832.  "A  debtor,"  they  said,4  "who  rinding 
himself  in  difficulty  or  even  insolvency,  but  so  circumstanced  as 
not  to  be  within  the  scope  of  the  bankruptcy  law,  is  at  present 
frequently  placed  in  a  distressing  situation  ;  however  willing  he 
may  be  to  do  substantial  justice  by  making  a  cession  of  his  pro- 
perty for  the  benefit  of  his  creditors,  he  is  often  unable  to  effect 
his  purpose.  If  he  offer  a  composition,  it  is  in  the  power  of  one 
or  two  of  the  creditors,  out  of  mere  caprice  or  in  the  expectation 
of  being  paid  in  full,  to  defeat  the  arrangement,  and  several  cases 
of  great  hardship  have  occurred,  when,  after  a  debtor  has  sur- 
rendered the  whole  of  his  estate  for  the  benefit  of  his  creditors,  he 
has  been  arrested  and  left  to  lie  in  prison,  without  the  means  of 
obtaining  his  liberation." 

It  would,  I  think,  be  true  to  say  that  it  was  this  branch  of 
English  law  which  was  the  most  injuriously  affected  by  the  abolition 
of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Council.  That  neither  the  Legislature, 
nor  the  common  law,  nor  equity,  had  succeeded  in  constructing  a 
satisfactory  body  of  law,  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  the  defects 
pointed  out  at  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  are,  to  a 
large  extent,  the  same  as  those  pointed  out  by  Brinklow  in  the 
sixteenth  century.5 

II 
MARITIME   LAW 

As  with  commercial,  so  with  maritime  law,  its  main  outlines 
were  beginning  to  assume  their  modern  aspect  during  this  period, 
This  fact  emerges  clearly  from  the  treatment  by  the  court  of 
Admiralty  and  by  the  writers  of  the  period  of  some  of  the  principal 
topics  of  this  branch  of  the  law.  The  topics  with  which  I  propose 
to  deal  are — The  Ownership  and  Possession  of  Ships  ;  the  Master 

1 9  William  III.  c.  29. 

2  The  need  for  some  legislation  is  illustrated  by  a  petition  of  Robert  Ryves,  a 
goldsmith  who  had  been  ruined  by  the  stop  of  the  Exchequer  (above  186) ;  he  prayed 
that  the  king  would  interfere  to  make  a  creditor  accept  a  composition  approved  by  all 
the  others,  S.P.  Dom.  1676-1677  158. 

3  Above  231-232. 

4  Fourth  Report,  Parliamentary  Papers  1831-1832  Pt.  I.  14. 
'Above  232. 


246  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and  Crew  ;  the  Contract  of  Carriage  ;  and,  Some  Incidents  of  the 
Contract  of  Carriage. 


The  Ownership  and  Possession  of  Ships 

The  usual  methods  of  acquiring  the  ownership  of  a  ship  were 
either  by  building  her,  or  by  capture  followed  by  condemnation,1 
or  by  transfer  from  an  owner.  Such  a  transfer  was  usually  effected 
by  bill  of  sale,  or  by  ordinary  deed  followed  by  delivery.  The 
delivery  was  the  essential  matter ; 2  but  it  could  be  effected  by 
bill  of  sale  without  delivery  when  the  ship  was  at  sea.8  Some- 
times the  seller  warranted  his  title  to  the  ship.4  Suits  turning  upon 
questions  of  title  occur  fairly  frequently — many  of  them  are  suits 
by  the  true  owner  against  the  purchasers  from  pirates.5  They 
illustrate  the  force  of  Malynes'  caution  to  the  merchants,  that  it  is 
"dangerous  to  fraight  unknown  ships  which  maybe  subject  to 
other  men's  actions,  and  that  in  many  places  where  wind  and 
weather  may  command  them  to  enter." 6  In  order  to  settle 
questions  of  title,  the  court  of  Admiralty  would  declare  the  title 
at  the  suit  of  a  plaintiff  who  complained  that  another  was  wrong- 
fully asserting  title  to  his  ship.7 

A  claim  upon  a  ship  might  arise  as  the  result  of  the  hypotheca- 
tion of  the  ship  by  the  owner  or  master  to  a  creditor,8  or,  at  this 
period,  from  the  fact  that  the  claimant  had  done  work  upon  the 

1  Raylestone  c.  Guerson  (1601)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  201 ;  cp. 
Dasent  vi  106-107,  2°7  (I557)  f°r  two  cases  turning  on  the  question  of  title  by  capture. 

2  "  The  selling  of  a  ship  is  not  a  sufficient  course  to  alienate  the  same  ;  but  the 
quiet  possession  thereof  must  be  delivered  upon  the  sale  made,"  Malynes,  op.  cit.  123  ; 
this  was  contrary  to  the  common  law  rule  that  the  property  passed  by  the  sale  without 
delivery,  and  so  the  common  law  courts  made  the  different  rule  applied  by  the 
Admiralty  the  ground  for  issuing  writs  of  prohibition,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty 
(S.S.)  ii  xlix-1. 

3 Ibid  i  98 — a  case  of  1540  in  which  the  custom  is  thus  stated,  "that  all,  and 
every  contracte  or  sale  of  any  shipe  goods  wares  or  other  merchandyses  made  or 
had  by  any  owner  .  .  .  thereof  to  any  merchaunte  or  other  person  .  .  .  and  (the 
buyer)  having  a  byll  of  sale  thereuppon  made  and  delyvered  to  hym  by  the  seller,  ys 
good  and  valuable  and  .  .  .  the  said  buyer  by  vertue  of  the  said  custome  and  delyvery 
of  the  said  byll  of  sayle  .  .  .  may  entre  and  take  possession  of  the  said  shipe  goods 
wares  and  merchandyses  so  sold  .  .  .  at  theyr  retorne  ad  portum  destinatum  withoute 
any  further  tradicion " ;  cp.  Dasent  xiii  215,  222  (1581)  for  a  case  turning  on  the 
transfer  of  a  ship. 

4  Browne  c.  Maye  (1551)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  16  is  a  case 
turning  on  such  a  warranty. 

BLudkyn  c.  Edmunds  (1546)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  141-143; 
Gelderc.  Worelond  (1552)  ibid  ii  82 ;  Officium  Dominic.  Goods  ex  A  Hamburgh  Ship 
(1554)  ibid  91 ;  Officium  Domini  c.  The  Eugenius  (1556)  ibid  99;  Dasent  ix  73  (1575- 
1576) ;  x  102  (1577)- 

6  Lex  Mercatoria  124;  see  Poyntell  c.  De  Billota  (1555)  Select  Pleas  of  the 
Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  94  for  a  case  which  illustrates  the  force  of  Malynes'  remark. 

7  Kinge  c.  Gomez  (1596)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  179. 

8  For  such  instruments  see  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  62-63,  n  69. ;  for 
the  powers  of  the  master  to  hypothecate  see  below  249. 


OWNERSHIP  OF  SHIPS  247 

ship.1  In  such  a  case  the  creditor  could  realize  his  debt  by  arrest- 
ing the  ship,  and  taking  the  necessary  proceedings  in  the  court 
of  Admiralty.  The  court  could  order  sale  and,  if  there  was 
more  than  one  creditor,  distribute  the  proceeds  among  them.2  If 
it  was  a  part  owner  who  had  thus  pledged  his  share,  the  others 
could  intervene  and  pay  out  the  creditors.3  In  that  case  they 
could  recover  against  their  partner  the  amount  which  they  had 
thus  paid,  in  accordance  with  the  ordinary  rules  relating  to  partner- 
ships.4 

Generally  ships  were  owned  in  common  by  two  or  more  persons. 
The  frequency  with  which  this  occurred  had  given  rise  to  some 
definite  rules  as  to  their  rights  inter  se.  The  co-owners  were  of 
course  entitled  to  share,  in  proportion  to  their  shares,  in  any 
profits  made  by  the  ship,  or  in  any  compensation  to  which  the 
ship  was  entitled  for  wrongs  committed  against  her.5  Conversely, 
all  the  owners  were  liable  for  wrongs  committed  by  the  ship,8 
or  for  money  spent  upon  necessary  repairs.  If  one  part  owner 
made  necessary  repairs,  and  the  other  delayed  to  pay  for  four 
months,  he  lost  his  share " — a  severe  rule  founded  on  a  passage  in 
the  Digest  relating  to  the  repair  of  houses,s  which  was  not  followed 
in  later  law.9  More  difficult  questions  arose  when  the  co-owners 
disagreed  as  to  the  employment  of  the  ship.  It  was  settled  that 
the  disagreement  of  one  co-owner  could  not  force  the  ship  to  be 
idle.  The  rule  was  that  it  must  make  at  least  one  voyage  "  upon 
their  common  charges  and  adventures  "  ;  but  that  afterwards,  the 
partner  who  refused,  must  either  sell  his  share  to  the  others,  or 
allow  them  to  sail  the  ship.10     In  the  latter  case  he  must  share  in 

1  Simondson  c  Manelli  (1597)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  185 ;  but  in 
later  times  the  courts  of  common  law  regarded  such  contracts,  if  made  in  England 
with  the  owner,  as  giving  rise  to  a  merely  personal  liability,  and  so  they  prohibited 
proceedings  taken  by  such  creditors  in  the  Admiralty  against  the  ship,  Abbott,  Merchant 
Ships  and  Seamen  (3rd  ed.,  1808)  137-142 ;  I  have  purposely  chosen  an  early  edition 
of  this  book,  as  it  represents  the  law  as  it  existed  before  the  era  of  extensive  legislative 
change  began  ;  for  maritime  liens  generally  see  below  270-273. 

■  Re  Lappage  (1538)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  6g,  70. 

3  Cogley  c.  Taylor  (1548)  ibid  ii  7. 

*Thus  Welwod,  Abridgment  of  all  Sea  Lawes  Tit.  xv,  says  that,  if  an  owner  has 
been  forced  to  pay  on  a  contract  made  by  the  master,  "  the  rest  of  the  owners  .  .  . 
shall  relieve  this  man  pro  rata  of  their  portions" ;  for  Welwod's  book  see  vol.  v  n, 

131,  134- 

5Cougham  c.  Kindt  (1600)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  198-199. 

6  Below  252,  267;  Malynes,  op.  cit,  121.  7  Ibid  123. 

8  Dig.  17.  2.  52.  10.  9  Abbot,  Merchant  Ships  and  Seamen  (3rd  ed.)  83-84. 

10  Malynes,  op.  cit  120-121 ;  Welwod,  op.  cit,  40,  41 ;  the  rules  that  one  voyage 
must  be  made  was  not  followed  by  the  later  English  law,  Abbott,  op.  cit.  91 ;  as  is 
there  pointed  out,  "  the  old  rule  appears  to  have  been  framed  with  a  view  to  the  interest 
of  the  master,  who  in  former  times  was  a  principal  owner,  and  was  the  person  who, 
with  the  pecuniary  assistance  of  the  other  owners,  generally  caused  the  ship  to  be 
built  in  the  expectation  of  being  employed  in  the  command ;  an  expectation  which 
might  be  defeated,  if  the  others  could  sell  their  shares  to  strangers,  who,  acquiring  a 
majority  of  interest  might  appoint  a  friend  of  their  own." 


248  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  expense  of  fitting  the  ship  up  for  the  voyage ;  he  was  neither 
liable  for  the  losses  nor  entitled  to  the  profit  of  the  voyage ; x  but 
in  case  the  ship  perished  the  other  partners  were  liable  to  him  for 
the  value  of  his  share.2  The  court  of  Admiralty  would  in  such  a 
case  make  the  co-owners  give  him  security  for  the  value  of  his 
share.3  Should  the  majority  of  the  co-owners  refuse  to  continue 
in  partnership  with  the  minority,  they  must  all  agree  to  sell  at 
a  value,  or  to  employ  the  ship  on  a  voyage.  If  this  could  not 
be  done,  recourse,  at  this  period,  could  be  had  to  the  court  of 
Admiralty,  who  could  settle  the  matter  on  equitable  terms.4  In 
later  law,  apparently,  the  only  remedy  of  the  minority  was  to  sell 
their  shares  to  another.5 

The  Master  and  Crew 

Welwod 6  describes  for  us  the  ordinary  complement  of  a  trad- 
ing ship  of  this  period  as  follows  :  (i)  The  master — "he  who  bears 
charge  over  all  the  ship  "  ;  (2)  The  steersman,  who  was  often  the 
same  person  as  the  master — "he  who  directs  the  ship  in  the  course 
of  her  voyage"  ;  (3)  the  master's  mate;  (4)  the  shipwright — "he 
who  attends  upon  the  mending  of  the  faulty  parts  of  the  ship  "  ; 

(5)  the  boatsman — "he  who  bears  the  charge  of  the  ship's  boat"  ; 

(6)  the  clerk — "  whose  office  is  to  write  up  and  make  account  of 
all  things  received  or  delivered  in  the  ship,  together  with  all  the 
ordinary  and  needful  expenses  made  upon  ship  and  kippage  "  ;  (7) 
the  cook — "a  most  necessary  member  as  long  as  there  will  be 
bellies  "  ;  (8)  the  ship's  boy — "  who  keeps  her  continually  in  har- 
bours "  ;  (9)  the  mariners. 

Here  we  need  only  consider  the  legal  position  of  the  master 
and  the  mariners. 

The  master's  relation  to  the  owner  was  determined  partly  by 
the  terms  of  the  contract  of  employment,  and  partly  by  the  com- 
mon law  of  the  sea.7  The  common  law  of  the  sea  gave  him  ordin- 
ary powers  to  freight  the  ship,  to  take  passengers,  to  provide 
necessaries,  and  to  do  ordinary  repairs.8     It  also  gave  him  extra- 

1  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121. 

2  Ibid.  The  rule  was  justified  on  the  ground  of  public  policy — "  ships  were  made 
and  invented  in  common  for  the  use  of  all  men  .  .  .  and  ordained  for  sailing,  and  not 
to  be  idle  and  unoccupied." 

3  Abbott,  op.  cit.  85 ;  see  ibid  87-90  for  the  controversy  as  to  the  power  of  the 
Admiralty  to  take  these  stipulations,  which  was  ultimately  settled  in  George  II. 's  reign 
in  favour  of  the  Admiralty. 

4  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121 ;  Welwod,  op.  cit.  41.  "Abbot,  op.  cit.  91. 
8  Op.  cit.  Tit.  vi :  "  Of  persons  ordinary  in  ships  "                     7Ibid  Tit.  viii. 

8 Ibid;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121,  gives  the  practical  advice  that,  "it  is  very  con- 
venient if  the  owners  be  in  place  that  the  master  do  not  let  the  ship  to  freight,  or 
undertake  any  voyage  without  the  privity  knowledge  and  advice  of  the  owners  or 
some  of  them  ";  see  Thomas,  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls,  243-245. 


THE  MASTER  AND  CREW  249 

ordinary  powers  to  borrow  money  in  a  foreign  country  for  the 
needs  of  the  ship,  and,  for  that  purpose,  to  hypothecate  ship  and 
cargo  or  freight.1  It  would  seem  that  these  powers  were  recog- 
nized in  the  Middle  Ages  in  the  commercial  courts  of  the  Italian 
cities  ;  and  that  the  transactions  themselves  were  really  a  variety 
and  a  development  of  the  loan  on  bottomry.2  The  debt  so  con- 
tracted took  precedence  of  all  other  charges  on  the  ship ; 3  and,  as 
in  the  case  of  the  loan  on  bottomry,  the  money  borrowed  was  not 
repayable  unless  the  ship  reached  its  destination.  Further,  the 
master  had  the  power,  in  case  of  necessity,  to  sell  the  cargo  or  the 
ship.4 

When  the  master  had  acted  within  the  scope  of  the  powers 
conferred  upon  him  by  his  contract  of  employment,  or  by  the  law, 
the  creditor  could  enforce  his  claims  against  either  the  owner  or 
the  master ; 5  and,  conversely,  the  owner  could  enforce  any  rights 
of  this  kind  acquired  by  the  master.0  Thus  contracts  made  by  the 
master  bound  the  owner  even  though  he  had  not  consented  to 
them,  and  even  though  any  property  acquired  under  them  had 
been  appropriated  by  the  master."  It  is  clear  that  this  is  an  ex- 
tension of  the  principle  of  agency  as  recognized  by  the  common 
law  at  this  period.  We  have  seen  that,  as  in  the  Middle  Ages, 
the  common  law  made  the  principal  liable  only  if  he  had  expressly 
authorized  or  subsequently  ratified  the  act  done.8  But,  according 
to  maritime  law,  he  was  liable  also  for  acts  done  by  the  agent 
within  the  scope  of  his  apparent  authority.  This  was  a  departure 
from  common  law  principles  which,  even  at  the  beginning  of  the 
nineteenth  century,  Abbott  thought  it  necessary  to  explain  and 


1  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  viii ;  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  92-93  (1541) — 
hypothecation  of  ship  and  freight  in  Sicily  by  the  master ;  ibid  ii  68  (1538) ;  ibid  ii 
191-192  (1599) — sentence  of  condemnation  for  money  due  upon  an  hypothecation  by 
the  master. 

2  Bensa,  Histoire  du  contrat  d'assurance  au  moyen  age  (French  tr.)  14,  15  ;  for 
the  development  of  the  contracts  of  bottomry  and  respondentia  see  below  261-263. 

3  Ibid  15,  citing  Pegolotti,  La  practica  della  mercatuera  cxxx  p.  132. 

4  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  viii ;  "  or  to  sell  some  of  the  merchants  goods,  provided 
that  the  highest  price  that  the  rest  of  the  goods  is  sold  for  at  the  market  be  repaid  to 
the  merchant :  which  being  done,  the  freight  of  those  goods  so  sold  and  repaid,  shall 
be  repaid  by  the  master  to  the  owner  of  the  ship  .  .  .  except  the  ship  perish  in  the 
voyage  ;  in  which  case  only  the  price  that  the  sold  goods  were  bought  for  shall  be 
rendered,"  ibid. 

5  Ibid  Tit.  xv. 

6  Ibid ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121 — "  because  herein  they  do  represent  and  undertake 
the  person  of  the  master,  ard  these  privileges  are  granted  to  the  owners  for  the  good 
of  the  common  wealth  and  the  augmentation  of  traffic." 

7  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xv ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121 — "  if  there  were  cause  of  mend- 
ing the  ship,  and  the  master  should  spend  the  same  another  way,  the  owner  is  to 
satisfy  the  creditor  notwithstanding  "  ;  it  was  otherwise  if  the  master  was  acting 
beyond  his  powers,  e.g.  if  he  borrowed  money  to  mend  a  ship  which  did  not  need 
mending. 

8  Above  227-228. 


250  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

justify.1  We  shall  see  that  the  justification  which  he  put  for- 
ward— the  agent  "  is  seldom  of  ability  to  make  good  a  loss  of 
any  considerable  amount " — is  in  reality  the  substantial  basis  of 
the  extensive  modification  of  common  law  principles,  which  is  in- 
volved in  the  modern  doctrine  of  the  employer's  liability  for  the 
torts  of  his  employe.2 

As  in  the  case  of  the  contracts  of  his  employes,  so  in  the  case 
of  their  torts,  the  liability,  according  to  maritime  law,  of  the 
master  or  owner  was  also  somewhat  different  from  his  liability  at 
common  law.  We  have  seen  that  at  common  law  the  master  or 
principal  was  only  liable  if  he  had  previously  authorized  or  subse- 
quently ratified  the  tort.3  But  according  to  maritime  law  the 
liability  of  the  master  of  a  ship  was  more  extensive ;  and,  at  the 
end  of  this  period,  it  was  recognized  (after  some  hesitation)  that 
the  owner  also  was  subject  to  this  extended  liability.  I  shall  con- 
sider firstly  the  case  of  the  master  of  the  ship,  and  secondly  the 
case  of  the  owner. 

(i)  It  was  quite  clear  that  the  master  was  liable  to  the  mer- 
chant and  passengers,  not  only  for  his  own  torts,4  but  also  for  the 
torts  of  the  crew.  He,  as  well  as  the  actual  tort  feasor,5  was  liable  ; 
and  liable,  some  said,  to  pay  double  the  damage.6  This  extension 
of  the  master's  liability  was,  to  a  certain  extent,  based  upon  the 
Roman  rule  as  to  the  quasi-delictual  liability  of  nautae  caupones 
and  stabularii  for  the  delicts  of  their  employes.7  It  was  justified,  as 
the  principle  of  employer's  liability  is  justified  to-day,  on  the  ground 
of  public  policy.  Welwod  explains  that  this  liability  is  "most 
justly  laid  upon  the  master,  because  he  ought  to  hire  good  men. 
.  .  .  For  it  is  in  his  own  free  will  to  choose  his  company,  and  he 
should  not  be  ignorant  of  the  men  he  hath  to  do  with ;  otherwise, 

1  Op.  cit.  123-124 — "  the  great  responsibility  which  the  laws  of  commercial  nat;ons 
cast  upon  the  owners  for  the  acts  of  the  master  .  .  .  has  appeared  to  many  persons  at 
first  view,  to  be  a  great  hardship;  but  ...  it  should  always  be  remembered  that  the 
master  is  .  .  .  appointed  by  the  owners ;  and  by  their  appointment  .  .  .  they  hold 
him  forth  to  the  public  as  a  person  worthy  of  trust  and  confidence;  and  if  the  mer- 
chants .  .  .  could  not  have  redress  against  those  who  appointed  him,  they  would 
often  have  just  reason  to  complain  that  they  had  sustained  an  irreparable  injury 
through  the  negligence  or  mistake  of  the  owners  ;  as  the  master  is  seldom  of  ability 
to  make  good  a  loss  of  any  considerable  amount." 

2  Below  474-475,  477-479- 

3  Above  227-228.  4  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  ix. 
8  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  197-198  (1600). 

6  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  ix ;  but  Malynes,  op.  cit.  103,  dees  not  say  that  the  matter 
is  liable  to  pay  double. 

'Dig.  4.  9. 1.  2. — "  Qui  sunt  igitur  teneantur,  videndum  est.  Ait  praetor  •  nautae.' 
Nautam  accipere  debemus  eum  qui  navem  exercet :  quamvis  nautas  appellantur  omnes, 
qui  navis  na  igandae  causa  in  nave  s-int :  sed  de  exercitore  solummodo  praetor  sentit. 
Nee  enim  debet,  inquit  Pomponius,  per  remigem  aut  mesonautam  obligari,  sed  per  se 
vel  per  navis  magistrum :  quamquam  si  ipse  alicui  e  nautis  committi  jussit,  sine  dubio 
debeat  obligari  "  ;  the  idea  seems  to  have  been  that  the  master  was  an  "  exercitor  " 
qua  the  crew, 


THE  MASTER  AND  CREW  251 

if  the  master  were  not  so  obliged  .  .  .  there  would  be  a  great  oc- 
casion of  stealth  and  spoil." *  And  it  would  seem  that  his  liability 
was  even  more  stringent  than  that  cast  upon  an  employer  in  our 
modern  law.  Malynes  and  Welwod  tell  us  that  for,  "whatsoever 
shall  happen  through  fault  negligence  or  chance  which  might  be 
avoided,  or  if  it  be  done  by  the  passengers  or  other  than  himself  or 
his  company,  the  master  is  answerable."2  The  words  "chance 
which  might  be  avoided  "  show  that  he  was  not  quite  in  the  posi- 
tion of  an  insurer — in  fact  to  have  held  him  liable  as  an  insurer 
would  have  been  contrary  to  the  principles  of  civil  liability  recog- 
nized by  the  court  of  Admiralty.3  But  his  liability  for  damage 
done  by  passengers  or  third  persons  put  him  almost  into  that  posi- 
tion, as  was  shown  by  the  case  of  Morse  v.  Slue}  In  that  case  an 
action  was  brought  against  the  master  of  a  ship  lying  in  the  Thames 
by  the  owner  of  goods  on  board  the  ship,  because  these  goods  had 
been  stolen  by  thieves.  The  master  proved  that  the  ship  had  been 
guarded  in  the  usual  way.  It  was  ultimately  held  that  the  case 
must  be  decided  on  common  law  principles,  because  the  ship  was 
not  within  the  jurisdiction  of  the  court  of  Admiralty,  and  that  the 
master  was  liable  as  a  carrier.5  But  it  was  quite  arguable  that, 
even  on  the  principles  applied  by  the  court  of  Admiralty,  he  could 
have  been  held  to  be  liable.6  According  to  these  principles  his 
liability  would  depend  upon  whether  he  could  show  that  the 
damage  was  quite  unavoidable. 

(ii)  The  question  whether  the  owner  was  liable  for  the  torts 
of  the  master  or  crew  was  by  no  means  clearly  settled  at  the  be- 
ginning of  this  period 

The  common  lawyers  held  that  he  was  not  liable.  In  i6c67 
it  was  argued  that  the  owner  was  liable  in  a  case  in  which  an 
English  ship,  provided  with  letters  of  marque,  had  attacked  a 
vessel  belonging  to  a  country  with  which  England  was  at  peace. 
It  was  said  that  in  matters  which  affected  public  policy  owners 
were  at  civil  law  always  liable  for  the  torts  of  their  employes ; 
and  the  analogy  of  the  common  law  liability  of  the  custom  house 

1  Op.  cit.  Tit.  ix ;  cp.  Dig.  4.  9. 1. 1. — "  Maxima  utilitas  esthujus  edicti,  quia  necesse 
est  plerumque  eorum  fidem  sequi  et  res  custodiae  eorum  committere.  Ne  quisquam 
putet  graviter  hoc  adversus  eos  constltutum :  nam  est  in  ipsorum  arbitrio,  ne  quern 
recipiant,  et  nisi  hoc  esset  statutum,  materia  darttur  cum  furibus  adversus  eos  quos 
recipiunt  coeundi,  cum  ne  nunc  quidem  abstineant  hujusmodi  fraudibus."  It  is  inter- 
esting to  observe,  Dig.  4.  9.  7.  2.,  that  "  si  quid  nautae  inter  se  damni  dederint  hoc  ad 
exercitorem  non  pertinet  " — an  anticipation  of  the  doctrine  of  common  employment. 

3  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  ix  ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  103. 

3  Below  258-259. 

*  Repoited  2  Keb.  866 ;  3  Keb.  72,  112,  135  ;  2  Lev.  69 ;  1  Vent.  190,  238 ; 
1  Mod.  85  ;  T.  Raym.  220 ;  the  date  of  the  case  is  1672. 

sSee  1  Mod.  85  n.  a. 

6  See  the  argument  for  the  pbintiff  in  3  Keb.  11?,  113. 

7  Waltham  v.  Mulgar,  Moore  (K.B.)  776. 


252  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

officer  and  the  marshal  was  relied  on.1  But  Popham  denied  that 
any  such  general  principle  existed  at  common  law.  He  admitted 
that  a  master  might  be  liable  if,  having  sent  his  servant  to  do  one 
kind  of  illegal  act,  the  servant  had  done  another  kind  of  illegal 
act :  he  would  not  be  liable  if,  having  sent  his  servant  to  do  a 
legal  act,  the  servant  had  done  an  illegal  act.2  The  civilians,  on 
the  other  hand,  were  not  quite  clear  as  to  the  extent  of  the 
owner's  liability.  According  to  Welwod  and  Malynes  the  owner 
was  not  liable  for  the  master's  torts ; 3  though  he  might  be  liable 
for  the  torts  of  a  mariner,  especially  if  the  mariner  had  actually 
been  hired  by  himself.4  But  others  thought  that  the  owner  was 
liable  to  the  merchant  for  the  negligence  either  of  the  master  or  of 
the  crew  ; 5  and  in  support  of  this  view  the  quasi-delictual  liability 
for  the  damage  done  by  nautae  caupones  and  stabularii  imposed 
upon  the  exercitor,  i.e.  the  owner  or  person  on  whose  account  the 
ship  was  worked,  could  be  adduced.6  Whether  on  this  ground  or 
not,  owners  were  held  liable  by  the  court  of  Admiralty  for  the 
damage  done  by  their  employes  in  the  late  sixteenth  and  early 
seventeenth  centuries.7 

We  have  seen  that,  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the 
strict  common  law  principles  which  governed  the  liability  of 
masters  or  principals  for  the  acts  of  their  servants  or  agents,  were 
wholly  unsuited  to  the  commercial  condition  of  the  country.8  It 
is  not  surprising,  therefore,  that  Holt  should  find  in  these  civil  law 
principles  a  useful  technical  means  of  making  a  very  necessary 
development  in  the  law.  In  the  case  of  Boson  v.  Sandford 9  he 
held  that  a  shipowner  was  liable  for  damage  to  goods  caused  by 
the  master's  negligence ;  and  he  based  his  decision  on  the  broad 
principle  that,  "whoever  employs  another  is  answerable  for  him, 
and  undertakes  for  his  care  to  all  that  make  use  of  him."  10  It  is 
clear  that  this  principle  was  applicable  to  other  cases  besides  cases 

1  "  Et  les  Civilians  argueont  en  Court,  et  Dodderidge  prist  un  diversity  que  en 
affaires  publick  les  servants  acts  chargeront  le  master  et  le  master  respoignera  pur  son 
servant.  Et  il  cite  7  Eliz.  Dyer  lou  le  servant  conceal  customes  :  et  39  H.  6  lou  le 
servant  misexecute  l'office  de  Marshal  (for  some  of  these  cases  see  vol.  iii  387).  Et 
quia  traffique  est  publick  entercourse  pur  le  weal  del  Realm,  cestuy  que  mista  un  neive 
en  traffique  doit  provider  servants  que  ne  fairont  publique  offences  "  ;  later  "  Dodderidge 
dit  que  le  Ley  Civil  est  que  la  master  respondra  en  touts  publique  cases,"  ibid  at 

P-  777- 

2  "  II  prist  cest  rule  lou  le  master  mista  son  servant  de  faire  un  act  illoyal,  le 
master  respondra  pur  le  servant  sil  mistake  en  le  feazance  del  act,  mes  lou  il  mista  son 
servant  de  faire  un  loyal  act  come  icy  de  prender  les  biens  des  enemies  le  Roy,  et  il 
prist  les  biens  des  amies,  le  master  ne  respondra." 

3  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xv  ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121.  4  Ibid 

6  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  131  (1544-1545) — in  such  a  case  the  master 
and  crew  were  liable  to  indemnify  the  owner. 

s  Above  250  n.  7;  cp.  Marsden,  Collisions  at  sea  (6th  ed.)  63  n.  1. 

7  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxi  (1575-1576)  lxxvi. 

8  Above  228-229.  9  (1691)  2  Salk.  440  ;  3  Mod.  321. 
10  2  Salk.  440. 


THE  MASTER  AND  CREW  253 

of  shipowner  and  master ;  and  we  shall  see  that  Holt,  by  giving 
it  a  wide  extension,  introduced  into  English  law  the  modern 
principle  of  the  employer's  liability  for  the  torts  of  his  employe, 
and  helped  to  free  the  common  law  from  the  restrictions  imposed 
by  the  idea  that  the  employer's  liability  for  these  torts  depended 
solely  on  the  law  of  agency.1 

I  think  therefore,  that  the  recognition  by  the  common  law  of 
these  new  principles  owed  something  to  the  rules  which,  from  the 
basis  of  the  civil  law,  had  been  evolved  in  the  court  of  Admiralty,2 
It  was,  in  fact,  only  natural  that,  as  the  necessities  arising  from  a 
larger  commerce  were  felt  in  the  court  of  Admiralty  at  an  earlier 
period  than  in  the  courts  of  common  law,  we  should  get  in  the 
court  of  Admiralty  the  earliest  traces  of  the  existence  of  a  prin- 
ciple of  modern  law  which  was  introduced  in  consequence  of  those 
necessities.  In  the  court  of  Admiralty  the  principle  was  based  on 
the  technical  reasoning  and  analogies  derived  from  the  civil  law : 
at  the  common  law  it  was  based  mainly  on  expediency,  and 
perhaps  to  some  extent  upon  certain  exceptions  to  the  mediaeval 
rules  which  governed  an  employer's  liability.  Here,  as  in  other 
cases,  ideas  were  borrowed  almost  unconsciously,  when  the 
influence  of  the  commercial  business,  of  which  the  common  law 
courts  had  deprived  the  court  of  Admiralty,  began  to  be  felt.  Of 
the  manner  in  which  these  principles  were  developed  by  the 
common  law  I  shall  speak  more  fully  in  the  following  chapter. 

The  master's  relation  to  his  crew  was  founded  mainly  on  the 
provisions  to  be  found  in  the  laws  of  Oleron.3  We  see  the  old 
rule  that  the  master  should  consult  with  his  crew  as  to  the  ex- 
pediency of  making  a  start  from  port,4  as  to  the  necessity  of 
making  a  jettison,5  or  of  borrowing  money  on  a  foreign  port.6 
We  see  the  old  rules  as  to  the  case  of  a  seaman  who  had  become 
sick  in  the  service  of  the  ship."  Similarly  the  law  as  to  rights 
and  duties  of  the  crew  were  founded  mainly  on  the  laws  of 
Oleron.  We  see  the  old  rule  that  the  mariner  was  entitled  to 
carry  a  small  portion  of  merchandize,  or  to  receive  compensation 
if  he  did  not.8  The  rule  was  still  maintained  that  if  the  ship  was 
cast  away,  so  that  no  freight  was  earned,  no  wages  were  payable 9 

1  Below  474-475. 

2  We  shall  see  that  there  are  certain  earlier  cases  in  which  a  larger  liability  had 
been  hinted  at,  below  453,  473  ;  but  it  was  in  the  case  of  Boson  v.  Sandford  2  Salk. 
440  that  the  new  principle  was  for  the  first  time  firmly  established,  below  474. 

3  Vol.  v  120-125.  *  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit,  viii.  5  Ibid  Tit.  xvii. 
6  Ibid  Tit  viii.                       7  Ibid  Tit.  x ;  vol.  v  121. 

8  Ibid  ;  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xi — "  a  mariner  may  either  keep  his  portage  in  his 
own  hand  or  put  forth  the  same  for  freight" 

9  Jonson  c.  Bannister  (1560)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  25 — "  That 
the  marrynors  gonners  and  other  ministers  whosoever  in  eny  ship  or  vessel  laboring 
and  travayling  upon  the  seaes  shall  as  well  abide  beare  and  suffer  thadventure  and 
losse  of  theire  wages  and  salarie  if  the  shippe  or  vessell  wherein  they  sayle  and  serve 


254  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

— "freight  is  the  mother  of  wages."  On  the  other  hand,  if  the 
voyage  was  abandoned,  half  wages  were  due ; x  and  these  rules 
existed  in  substantially  their  old  shape  down  to  the  passing  of  the 
Merchant  Shipping  Act  of  1854.2 

The  Contract  of  Carriage 

At  the  present  day  "  a  trading  ship  is  employed  by  virtue  of 
two  distinct  species  of  contract :  First,  the  contract  by  which  an 
entire  ship,  or  at  least  the  principal  part  thereof,  is  let  for  a 
determined  voyage  to  one  or  more  places  ;  this  is  usually  done  by 
a  written  instrument  signed  and  sealed,  and  called  a  charter  party. 
Secondly,  the  contract  by  which  the  master  or  owners  of  a  ship 
destined  on  a  particular  voyage,  engage  separately  with  a  number 
of  persons  unconnected  with  each  other,  to  convey  their  respective 
goods  to  the  place  of  the  ship's  destination.  A  ship  employed  in 
this  manner  is  usually  called  a  general  ship."3 

It  would  appear  from  Malynes  that  he  was  only  acquainted 
with  the  first  of  these  methods  of  employing  a  ship.  If  one 
merchant  could  not  load  the  ship,  several  joined  to  charter  her. 
No  ship,  he  says  should  be  freighted  without  a  charter  party,4 
and  bills  of  lading  should  be  drawn  up  to  declare  the  contents  of 
the  cargo,  and  to  bind  the  master  to  deliver  in  accordance  with  the 
charter  party.5  It  is  clear  from  his  account,  and  from  the  speci- 
mens of  these  documents  which  have  come  down  to  us  from  this 
period,  that  these  documents  had  almost  attained  their  modern 
form.0     Here  I  shall  first  of  all  say  something  of  the  charter  party 

by  mysadventure  of  the  seaes  or  tempest  do  perishe  in  that  viage  as  the  owners  and 
laders  shall  and  must  in  like  case  beare  suffer  and  sustayne  thadventure  of  theire  sayd 
shipp  and  goods  "  ;  lawyers  of  the  early  nineteenth  century  justified  the  rule  as  the 
counterpart  of  the  rule  that  gave  him  his  wages,  though  disabled  by  sickness  in  the 
service  of  the  ship — "  As  a  seaman  is  exposed  to  the  hazard  of  losing  the  reward  of 
his  faithful  service  during  a  considerable  period  in  certain  cases,  so  on  the  other  hand 
the  law  gives  him  his  whole  wages,  even  when  he  has  been  unable  to  render  his  ser- 
vice, if  his  inability  has  proceeded  from  any  hurt  received  in  the  performance  of  his 
duty,  or  from  natural  sickness  happening  to  him  in  the  course  of  the  voyage,"  Abbott, 
op.  cit.  424 ;  the  historical  reason  is  much  more  probably  to  be  found  in  the  fact 
stated  in  Jonson  v.  Bannister  that  the  seaman  took  a  share  in  the  adventure — he  was 
entitled  to  ship  goods  of  his  own  and  get  freight  for  them  ;  this  is  rendered  the  more 
probable  by  the  fact  that  other  rules  seem  to  assume  that  he  was  a  sharer  in  the 
adventure,  above  253  n.  8 ;  no  doubt  the  rule  was  retained  when  this  practice  became 
obsolete  in  order  to  induce  the  men  to  do  their  best  for  the  ship. 

1  Tye  c.  Spryngham  (1561)  ibid  ii  122-123 ;  Thorneton  c.  the  "  Elizabeth 
Bonaventure,"  and  Jobson  owner  (1565)  ibid  ii  131-132. 

2  17,  18  Victoria  c.  104  §  183  ;  reinacted  57,  58  Victoria  c.  60  §  157. 

3  Abbott,  op.  cit.  112. 

4 Op.  cit.  97;  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  vii — "and  this  charter  party,  among  all 
the  western  merchants,  and  those  of  the  great  ocean,  usually  is  made  to  perform  all 
things  requisite  by  the  laws  of  Oleron." 

8  Malynes,  op.  cit.  97. 

6  Ibid  op.  cit.  Part  I.  c.  xxi ;  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  35-37 
(1531) ;  81-83  (1538)— charter  parties  ;  ibid  i  61-62  (1538);  112-113  (1541);  126-128 
(1544-1546) ;  ii  59-64  (1549-1570) — bills  of  lading. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       255 

and  the  bill  of  lading  ;  and,  secondly,  of  the  rules  which  determined 
the  nature  of  the  obligations  of  the  parties  to  these  contracts  to 
carry. 

(i)  Under  the  ordinary  contract  of  charter  party  the  master 
or  owner  of  the  ship  acknowledges  that  he  has  let  the  ship  to  a 
merchant,  and  promises  to  make  the  ship  ready  by  a  fixed  date  to 
take  in  the  goods  provided  by  the  merchant  He  promises  that 
he  will  sail  with  the  first  convenient  wind  to  the  port  stipulated, 
and  that  he  will  deliver  the  goods  in  good  condition  to  the 
merchant  or  his  factor  in  accordance  with  the  bills  of  lading.  The 
ship  is  to  remain  at  that  port  for  a  fixed  period  to  take  in  such 
goods  as  the  merchant  or  the  factor  shall  load  in  her,  return  to 
the  port  from  which  she  started,  and  deliver  the  goods  in  good 
condition.  The  master  or  owner  also  covenants  that  the  crew  shall 
consist  of  so  many  persons,  shall  be  armed  in  such  a  way,  and  shall 
be  furnished  with  all  proper  gear.  The  merchant,  on  the  other  hand, 
covenants  with  the  master  or  owner  to  load  the  ship  within  the 
time  stipulated,  and  to  pay  so  much  a  ton  for  freight,  on  the  dis- 
charge of  the  goods,  and  other  customary  payments  such  as 
primage,1  petilodeminage a  or  pilotage,  and  average.3  Both  sides 
bound  themselves  in  a  penal  clause  to  fulfil  their  covenants  with 
the  addition,  Malynes  says,4  of  other  clauses  or  conditions  designed 
to  prevent  future  litigation.  Instances  of  such  other  conditions  to 
be  found  in  charter  parties  of  this  period  are  clauses  exempting 
the  owner  from  liability  for  accidents,5  providing  that  certain  mis- 
chances shall  constitute  a  general  average  loss,6  or  stipulating  that 
the  value  of  any  prizes  taken  by  the  ship  shall  be  distributed  in 
certain  proportions.7 

Probably  the  origins  of  the  bill  of  lading  are  to  be  found  in  the 
custom  of  entering  the  goods  shipped  on  the  ship's  book  or  register  ; 
and  the  rule,  resulting  therefrom,  that  the  owner  or  master  was  not 
liable  for  goods  not  so  entered.8  In  the  days  when  the  merchants 
travelled  with  their  goods  this  entry  would  be  sufficient.9  But 
when  the  merchant  ceased  to  travel,  and  sent  the  goods  to  a  given 
consignee,  separate  documents  would  obviously  become  essential ; 

1  A  small  payment  to  the  master  for  his  care  and  trouble,  Abbott,  op.  cit.  270 ; 
but  in  the  seventeenth  century  both  primage  and  average  were  explained  as  a  gratuity 
to  the  seamen  for  care  of  the  cargo,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxxi. 

2  I.e.  Petty  Lodemanage  or  pilotage. 

8  In  this  connection  the  word  average  "  denotes  several  petty  charges  which  are 
to  be  borne  partly  by  the  ship  and  partly  by  the  cargo,  such  as  the  expense  of  towing 
beaconage,  etc." ;  Abbott,  op.  cit  270,  271 ;  to  be  distinguished  from  general  average 
as  to  which  see  below  263-265. 

4  Op.  cit  100.  s  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  137  (1545). 

6  Ibid  ii  64  (1562).  7  Ibid  i  37  (1531). 

8  Bennett,  the  History  and  present  position  of  the  Bill  of  Lading  4-6. 

•See  Thomas,  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  244-245  for  a  case  of  1305-1306  which 
turns  on  this  custom. 


256  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

and  it  is  clear  that,  if  disputes  are  to  be  avoided,  it  will  be  desirable 
that  each  of  the  parties  interested,  the  consignor,  the  master  of  the 
ship,  and  the  consignee,  should  have  a  copy.1  The  first  of  these 
developments  had  taken  place  at  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth 
century.  The  bill  of  lading,  like  the  old  entry  on  the  ship's 
register,  was  the  only  evidence  of  the  goods  loaded ;  and  the 
owners  were  not  liable  for  any  goods  not  therein  contained.2  The 
second  took  place  in  the  course  of  the  same  century.  There  is  a 
clear  reference  to  bills  drawn  in  a  set  of  three  in  1539  ;3  and  it 
was  a  settled  custom  when  Malynes  wrote.  He  says  : i  "Of  these 
bills  of  lading,  there  is  commonly  three  bills  of  one  tenor  made  of 
the  whole  ship's  lading,  or  of  many  particular  parcels  of  goods,  if 
there  be  many  laders ;  and  the  mark  of  the  goods  must  therein  be 
expressed,  and  of  whom  received,  and  to  whom  to  be  delivered. 
These  bills  of  lading  are  commonly  to  be  had  in  print  in  all  places 
and  several  languages.  One  of  them  is  enclosed  in  the  letters 
written  by  the  same  ship,  another  bill  is  sent  overland  to  the  factor 
or  party  to  whom  the  goods  are  consigned,  the  third  remaineth 
with  the  merchant,  for  his  testimony  against  the  master,  if  there 
were  any  occasion  or  loose  dealing ;  but  especially  it  is  kept  for  to 
serve  in  case  of  loss,  to  recover  the  value  of  the  goods  of  the 
assurors  that  have  undertaken  to  bear  the  adventure  with  you." 

It  is  clear  from  this  passage  of  Malynes  that  when  he  wrote 
the  form  of  the  bill  of  lading  had  become  stereotyped  ;  and  this  is 
borne  out  by  the  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty.  The  earlier 
specimens  are  somewhat  informal  in  character ;  but,  by  the  middle 
of  the  sixteenth  century,  they  are  very  near  to  their  modern 
form.5  Thus  a  bill  of  lading  of  the  year  1 534 c  declares  that 
John  Desallez,  merchant  of  London,  has  loaded  at  Rouen  in  a  ship 
called  the  George  of  Legh,  the  master  of  which  is  Thomes  Karre, 
so  much  wine  and  so  many  apples,  marked  with  his  mark,  to  be 
carried  to  London,  "  exceptid  the  casalties  and  dangers  of  the 
sea."  The  master  promises  to  deliver  the  goods  to  the  said 
merchant,  his  factor,  or  assigns,  he  or  they  paying  the  freight, 
primage,  and  average. 

1  Bennett,  op.  cit.  6,  7. 

3  The  following  statement  was  made  in  1534  in  the  case  of  Chapman  c.  Peers, 
Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  44 — "  Proprietarii  et  magistri  seu  exercitores 
navium  aut  eorum  bursarii  non  tenentur  neque  debentur  aut  eorum  aliquis  non  ten- 
entur  aut  debet  respondere  pro  bonis  aut  rebus  in  navibus  suis  invectis  seu  impositis 
que  in  libro  raciocinii  Anglice  the  boke  of  ladvng  communiter  dicti  et  nuncupati  per 
dictosmercatores  aut  eorum  factores  non  inscribuntur  me.  cionantur  aut  inseruntur  "  ; 
see  Diamond  Alkali  Export  Corporation  v.  Bourgeois  [1921]  3  K.B.  at  p.  449  where 
McCardie,  J.,  accepts  this  view  of  the  origin  of  the  bill  of  lading. 

3  Select  Plea  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  89  ;  for  another  instance  of  the  year  1546 
see  ibid  127-128. 

4  Op.  cit.  97.  8  See  references  above  n.  3. 
6  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  61. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       257 

It  is  clear  from  the  form  of  the  bill  of  lading  that  the  parties 
intended  that  delivery  should  be  made  to  the  consignee,  to  whom 
the  bill  has  been  sent.  It  is  obvious,  therefore,  that  it  was  a 
document  entitling  the  consignee  to  the  goods,1  provided  that  he 
pays  the  freight.2  But  these  bills  usually  provided  that  delivery 
should  be  made  to  the  consignee  "or  his  assigns."  Hence,  if  it 
were  assigned,  the  assignee  could  demand  delivery.  In  other 
words  the  assignment  of  the  bill  of  lading  passed  the  property  in 
the  goods.  This  rule  was  probably  established  in  the  court  of 
Admiralty  in  the  sixteenth  century ; 3  and  it  was  accepted  by  the 
courts  of  common  law  in  1697.  Holt,  C.J.,  said  that  "the  con- 
signee of  a  bill  of  lading  has  such  a  property  as  that  he  may 
assign  it  over.  And  Shower  said  that  it  had  been  adjudged  in 
the  Exchequer."  * 

It  is  probable  that  the  court  of  Admiralty  was  prepared  to  go 
further,  and  hold  that  it  was  not  only  assignable  but  negotiable. 
In  Charles  I.'s  reign  a  shipmaster  was  sued  in  the  Admiralty  for 
delivering  a  bar  of  silver  to  one  who  had  fraudulently  obtained 
the  bill  of  lading.  Judgment  was  given  for  the  defendant ;  but 
the  owner  of  the  silver  got  a  prohibition  and  brought  an  action  at 
common  law.5  It  is  probably  this  action  of  the  common  law 
courts  which  has  prevented  a  bill  of  lading  from  becoming  a 
negotiable  instrument.  Though  it  resembles  a  negotiable  instru- 
ment in  the  mode  by  which  it  can  be  transferred,  it  lacks  the 
essential  quality  of  negotiability — a  bona  fide  holder  for  value 
cannot  get  a  good  title  from  a  holder  who  had  none,  and  it  is  not 
assignable  "  free  from  equities."  6  It  is  simply  a  contract  to  carry 
certain  goods  which  operates  as  a  document  of  title  to  these  goods. 
But  in  one  respect  the  court  of  Chancery  modified  the  strictness 
of  the  common  law  rules.  We  have  seen  that  it  gave  to  the 
unpaid  vendor  the  right  to  stop  the  goods  in  transitu  on  the 
bankruptcy  of  the  consignee."  But  as  yet  neither  the  common 
law  rules  as  to  bills  of  lading,  nor  the  doctrine  of  stoppage  in 
transitu,  have  been  elaborated.  This  will  be  the  work  of  the 
eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries. 

1  We  get  in  1544  and  1546,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  127,  128,  the 
proviso  that  if  one  bill  is  performed  the  others  are  to  lose  their  effect ;  as  Mr.  Bennett 
says,  op.  cit.  10,  "  these  provisions  seem  clearly  to  contemplate  the  transfer  of  the  bill 
of  lading  as  a  document  of  title  to  the  goods  shipped — if  it  had  not  been  customary  for 
the  delivery  of  the  goods  to  be  made  to  the  holder  of  the  bill  of  lading  the  words  which 
provide  that  if  one  bill  should  be  performed  the  others  should  be  of  none  effect,  would 
be  meaningless." 

2  See  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  no. 

3  See  Hurlocke  and  Saunderson  c.  Collett  (1539)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty 
(S.S.)  i  88,  89. 

4  Evans  v.  Marlett  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  271. 

5  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  boori. 

6  Above  166-167.  7  Above  243. 

VOL.   VIIL — 17 


258  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

(2)  The  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty,  and,  at  the  close 
of  this  period,  the  cases  decided  in  the  common  law  courts,  show 
that  the  obligations  undertaken  by  the  parties  to  the  contract  of 
carriage  were  giving  rise  to  a  number  of  definite  rules  of  law. 

The  master  or  owners  were  liable  if  they  failed  to  supply  the 
ship  at  the  stipulated  time.  In  such  a  case  the  merchant  could 
decline  to  employ  the  ship,  or,  if  he  employed  her,  he  was 
entitled  to  recover  any  damages  which  he  had  sustained  *  They 
were  also  liable  if  they  failed  to  deliver  the  goods,2  or  if  the  goods 
arrived  in  a  damaged  condition  owing  to  negligent  stowage,3  to 
the  unseaworthiness  of  the  ship,4  or  to  any  other  form  of  wrongful 
act ; 5  and  this  liability  for  the  safety  of  the  goods  lasted  till  the 
cargo  was  discharged  on  to  the  quay  or  into  a  lighter.6  We  shall 
see  that  losses  occurring  through  acts  done  to  preserve  the  ship 
and  cargo  were  governed  by  special  rules.7  But  how  far  the 
master  or  owners  were  liable  for  losses,  other  than  those  resulting 
from  acts  done  to  preserve  the  ship  and  cargo,  which  did  not  arise 
through  their  fault,  was  not  very  clearly  settled  in  this  period.8 
This  uncertainty  was  to  a  certain  extent  aggravated  by  the 
different  rules  laid  down  by  the  civilians  and  the  common  lawyers. 

The  civilians  naturally  grounded  liability  upon  dolus  or  culpa. 
Therefore  they  were  inclined  to  hold  that,  though  a  person  was 
liable  even  for  accidental  loss  if  he  contracted  to  be  so  liable,  he 
was  not  otherwise  liable.9  Thus  for  a  loss  arising  from  an  attack 
by  pirates,10  or  for  damage  done  by  rats  if  there  was  a  cat  on  board,11 

1  Malynes,  op.  cit.  98  ;  Welwod,  Tit.  vii — "  except  the  master  show  some  excuse 
of  a  notorious  necessity,  or  of  a  chance  that  could  not  be  eschewed  :  and  then  he  loseth 
only  his  freight  "  ;  see  Thomas,  Early  Mayor's  Court  Rolls  243-245. 

2  De  Neronia  c.  Burye  (1540)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  113  ; 
Symonds  c.  Danyell  (1541)  ibid  105-106  ;  Revell  c.  Bona  Stringar  (1562)  ibid  ii 
124-125. 

3  Ritzo  c.  Pignea  (1597)  ibid  ii  184-185  ;  Dybdale  c.  Holmes  (1556)  ibid  ii  101 
(bad  stowage). 

4  Borneley  c.  Troute  (1586)  ibid  ii  163-164  (unseaworthiness);  Welwod,  op.  cit. 
Tit.  ix. 

5  Arnolde  c.  Anthonison  (1551)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  14  (goods 
negligently  thrown  overboard);  in  Vawse  c.  Bygot  (1540)  ibid  i  110-111  there  is  a 
statement  of  the  general  principle — "  that  the  proprietary  master  or  mariner  of  the 
shippe  .  .  .  ought  and  is  bounden  ...  to  redeliver  the  same  goods  in  portu  destinato 
to  the  person  that  the  same  goods  were  consigned  unto  in  as  good  condicion  as  thei 
were  received  and  taken  into  the  shippe." 

6  Ladyngton  c.  Hussey  (1552)  ibid  ii  80-81.  7  Below  263-265. 

8  Bodacar  c.  Block  (1571)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  146 — liability 
for  non-delivery  though  the  loss  was  caused  by  tempest  and  pillage ;  cp.  ibid  i  137 
(x545) — a  clause  exempting  the  shipowner  from  liability  from  certain  accidents ;  cp. 
Taylor  c.  Pennincke  (1602)  ibid  ii  202-203— the  shipowner  specially  undertakes  all 
risks  ;  Jaques  c.  Hulson  (1545)  ibid  i  137 — absence  of  negligence  pleaded  as  a  defence  ; 
cp.  Welwod  Tit.  ix — the  master  is  only  liable  for  "  fault,  negligence  or  chance 
eschewable." 

6  Taylor  c.  Pennincke,  last  note.  10  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xviii. 

11  Ibid  Tit.  vii — "  the  master  also  must  be  answerable  for  that  harm  which  the  rats 
for  want  of  a  cat  do  in  the  ship  to  any  merchandise," 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       259 

he  would  not  be  liable.  But  the  common  law  did  not  ground  civil 
liability  upon  dolus  or  culpa.  It  grounded  it  upon  the  fact  that 
the  defendant  had  done  some  act  to  the  damage  of  the  plaintiff, 
under  such  circumstances  that  the  defendant,  either  by  his  own 
contract  or  by  the  law,  was  obliged  to  compensate  the  plaintiff.1 
It  followed  from  this  principle  that  a  bailee  was  not  excused  if  the 
property  entrusted  to  him  was  damaged  by  accident ;  and  this  strict 
rule  was  maintained  all  through  this  period.2  Now  a  carrier  is 
only  a  bailee  of  a  particular  kind.  It  followed  therefore  that  a 
carrier,  whether  by  land  or  water,  was  not  excused  merely  because 
the  goods  had  perished  without  his  fault — he  was  not  excused,  for 
instance,  if  they  had  been  stolen,  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  he  had 
taken  all  reasonable  precautions  against  thieves.3  The  result  was 
that  different  rules  were  applied  to  determine  the  carrier's  liability 
according  to  whether  the  loss  occurred  at  sea  and  therefore  within 
the  jurisdiction  of  the  Admiralty,  or  whether  it  occurred  within  the 
body  of  a  county  and  therefore  within  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
common  law  courts.4 

That  the  common  law  rules  were  felt  to  be  too  strict  is  clear 
from  Coke's  advice  to  bailees  to  make  special  contracts  limiting 
their  liability.5  His  advice  was  followed;6  and  both  the  incon- 
veniences resulting  from  the  strictness  of  the  common  law  rules, 
and  from  the  conflict  between  the  rules  of  the  common  law  and 
those  of  the  civil  law,  were  to  a  large  extent  obviated  by  the 
introduction,  into  charterparties  and  bills  of  lading,  of  clauses  ex- 
cluding the  liability  of  owners  and  masters  in  certain  cases. 

As  a  general  rule  neither  freight  nor  wages  were  due  if  the 
goods  were  not  carried  to  their  port  of  destination.7  Of  course 
much  depended  on  the  terms  of  the  particular  contract.  But  here 
again  there  was,  at  this  period,  a  divergence  between  the  rules  of 
the  common  law  and  the  rules  of  the  civil  law.      As  in  the  case  of 


1  Vol.  iii  375-377- 

2  Holmes,  Common  Law  178-180;  Southcot  v.  Bennet  (1601)  4  Co.  Rep.  83b; 
vol.  iii  344;  above  vol.  vii  451-452. 

3  Woodlife's  Case  (1597)  Moore  462  ;  Holmes,  op.  cit.  181 ;  Symons  v.  Darknoll 
(1628)  Palmer  523,  Kenrig  v.  Eggleston  (1648)  Aleyn  93,  cited  Holmes,  op.  cit.  191. 

4  This  is  brought  out  by  the  case  of  Morse  v.  Slue  (1672)  1  Mod.  85,  cited  Holmes, 
op.  cit.  192-195  ;  in  1  Mod.  85  n.  a  it  was  said  that,  "  the  master  could  not  avail 
himself  of  the  rules  of  the  civil  law,  by  which  masters  are  not  chargeable  pro  damno 
fatali." 

*Southcote's  Case  (16  ji)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  p.  84a. 

'  A  case  of  1554  is  the  earliest  case  of  a  bill  of  lading  in  which  the  exception  of 
perils  of  the  seas  occurs,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  61 ;  as  to  the  way  in 
which  this  exception  was  construed  in  later  times  see  Abbott,  op.  cit.  252  seqq. 

7  Above  253  n.  9 ;  cp.  Le  Buck  c.  Van  Voisdonck  (1554)  Select  Pleas  of  the 
Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  93 — a  decree  for  the  repayment  of  prepaid  freight  when  the  voyage 
had  not  been  performed ;  among  the  cases  on  the  early  court  rolls  of  the  Mayor's  Court 
at  pp.  192-193,  there  is  a  case  in  1305,  where  the  agreement  as  to  the  port  of  destination 
was  varied  by  the  shipper's  super  cargo. 


260  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

liability  for  damage  to  the  goods  carried,  so  in  respect  to  freight 
and  wages,  the  common  law  at  this  period  took  a  stricter  view  of 
the  obligation  of  the  ship  than  the  civil  law.  The  common  law 
judges  seem  to  have  held  that  the  ship  earned  no  freight,  even 
though  part  of  the  voyage  had  been  performed,  and  even  though 
the  failure  to  complete  it  was  caused  by  no  fault  of  the  master.1 
On  the  other  hand,  the  civil  law  held  in  such  a  case  that  freight 
and  therefore  wages  were  due  for  the  part  of  the  voyage  per- 
formed ; 2  and  it  is  this  more  equitable  principle  which  has  prevailed.3 
Similarly  Malynes  repeats  the  rule  laid  down  in  the  laws  of  Oleron 
that  if  the  ship  was  wrecked,  the  merchant  must  pay  freight  on  the 
goods  saved.4  He  must  also  pay  freight  if  the  ship  became  dis- 
abled, and  the  goods  were  transhipped  and  so  carried  to  their 
destination.5  Any  deviation  from  the  proper  route,  unless  caused 
by  inevitable  necessity,  was  a  breach  of  the  contract.6 

On  the  other  hand,  the  merchant  who  had  chartered  a  whole 
ship  must  provide  a  cargo  for  the  ship  at  the  day  appointed.7  He 
was  liable  to  pay  the  freight  stipulated,  whether  or  no  he  had 
filled  her  with  cargo  ; 8  and  the  master  could  refuse  to  deliver  the 
goods  until  his  freight  and  other  charges  were  paid.9  He  must 
pay  demurrage  if  he  delayed  to  load  the  ship  beyond  the  stipulated 
period ; 10  and  he  was  liable  for  any  damage  caused  to  the  ship  by 
the  character  of  the  cargo  with  which  he  had  loaded  her.11 

Some  of  the  cases  of  this  period,  which  relate  in  the  colourless 
language  of  the  pleader  the  history  of  the  ships  employed  under 
these  contracts  of  carriage,  contain  romances  of  the  sea  worthy  of 

1  Bright  v.  Cowper  (1612)  1  Brownlow  21 — voyage  not  completed  owing  to 
capture  by  pirates. 

2  Malynes,  op.  cit.  98 — "  but  if  the  ship  in  her  voyage  become  unable  without  the 
master's  fault  .  .  .  the  master  may  either  mend  his  ship  or  freight  another.  But  in 
case  the  merchant  agree  not  thereunto,  then  the  master  shall  at  least  recover  his  freight 
so  far  as  he  hath  deserved  it "  ;  Molloy  Bk.  II.  c.  4  §  7,  after  citing  the  case  of  Bright 
v.  Cowper,  says  that  it  would  have  been  decided  differently  by  the  civil  law,  see  the 
passage  cited  Abbott,  op.  cit.  313  ;  it  was  the  rule  laid  down  in  the  laws  of  Oleron  §  4, 
above  vol.  v  122. 

3  Anon.  (1701)  1  Ld.  Raym.  639;  Jones  v.  Hart  (1700)  ibid  739;  Abbott,  op.  cit. 
294  seqq. 

4  Op.  cit.  101 ;  vol.  v  122. 

5  Laws  of  Oleron  §  4,  vol.  v  122  ;  the  principle  was  followed  by  the  House 
of  Lords  in  Lutwidge  v.  Gray  (1737),  cited  Abbott,  op.  cit.  298-301. 

6  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  xlvi ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  121  ;  Early  Mayor's 
Court  Rolls  243. 

7  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  vii. 

8Coke  c.  Fliett  (1542)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  115;  Gourden  c. 
Lovelake  (1552)  ibid  ii  82-83. 

9Vawsec.  Bygot  (1540)  ibid  i  iio-ni ;  Bell  c.  Bryde  (1553)  ibid  ii  84 — "  whoso- 
ever receives  any  goods  out  of  any  ship  or  boat  at  the  place  of  their  discharge  is  bound 
first  and  before  all  to  provide  and  pay  the  freight  .  .  .  due  to  such  ship  or  boat  to  the 
master  purser  or  mariners  of  the  same,  immediately  after  the  discharge  of  such  goods, 
or  at  least  according  to  the  contract  of  affreightment  made  and  entered  into." 

10Thurstone  c.  More  (1557)  ibid  ii  98-99.  ll  Ibid. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       261 

Hakluyt's  pen.  Perhaps  the  best  is  that  related  in  the  last  of  Mr. 
Marsden's  Select  Pleas.1  A  London  ship  was  chartered  for  Lagos. 
While  off  Lagos  it  was  attacked  by  Portuguese,  captured,  and  the 
crew  confined  under  hatches.  The  crew  blew  up  the  deck  with 
gunpowder  and  with  it  their  captors,  and  so  regained  possession  of 
their  ship.  They  then  worked  the  crippled  ship  back  to  London 
with  her  cargo  intact.  It  is  satisfactory  to  learn  that  the  court 
gave  the  ship  half  her  freight  to  the  use  of  the  owners  and  crew. 

Some  Incidents  of  the  Contract  of  Carriage 

Under  this  head  I  shall  consider  certain  incidents  of  the  con- 
tract of  carriage  by  sea,  which,  in  this  period,  had  already  given 
rise  to  a  number  of  legal  rules. 

Bottomry  and  Respondentia. 

If  a  ship  is  in  a  foreign  port,2  either  the  owner  or,  in  case  of 
necessity,  the  master,3  can  borrow  money  on  the  security  of  the 
ship,  or  of  ship  cargo  and  freight.  A  loan  thus  contracted  is  called 
a  loan  upon  " bottomry" — a  Flemish  term  derived  from  the  figura- 
tive use  of  the  bottom  or  keel  to  express  the  whole  ship.4  Simi- 
larly the  owner  of  the  cargo,  or  the  master  in  case  of  necessity, 
could  borrow  money  on  the  security  of  the  cargo  laden  on  the  ship. 
To  such  a  loan  the  term  "  respondentia  "  is  applied.5  In  both  cases 
the  lender  can  only  recover  the  money  lent  if  the  ship  arrives  safely 
at  her  destination ; 6  and,  because  the  lender  takes  the  risks  of  the 
voyage,  the  interest  charged  is  proportionately  high.7 

The  term  bottomry  first  occurs  in  the  records  of  the  court  of 
Admiralty  in  I  593  ; 8  and  we  have  a  reference  to  the  contract  of 
respondentia  (though  not  under  that  name)  in  Malynes'  work.9 
But  both  contracts  were  well  enough  known  in  Italy  in  the  four- 
teenth century  ; 10  and,  in  their  modern  form,  they  are  developments 
of  very  much  older  contracts.  In  Greek  law,  in  Roman  law  under 
the  name  of  pecunia  trajectitia,  and  in  early  mediaeval  law,  we  meet 
with  contracts  of  loan,  under  which  the  money  lent  was  only  repay- 
able if  the  ship  arrived  safely.11  But  these  earlier  contracts  differ 
from  the  later  contracts  of  bottomry  and  respondentia.      M.  Bensa 

'Steveins  c.  Savidge  (1602)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  205-206. 

2  Smith,  Mercantile  Law  (nth  ed.)  i  576,  577  n.  g.  3  Above  248-249. 

4  Cargo  ex  Sultan  (1859)  S\v.  Ad.  at  p.  510 ;  cp.  The  Atlas  (1827)  2  Hagg.  Ad.  at 
p.  58. 

5  Ibid.  *  Smith,  Mercantile  Law  i  574  ;  cp.  Bl.  Comm.  ii  458,  459. 

7  Smith,  Mercantile  Law  i  575  ;  Bl.  Comm.  ii  459 ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  122. 

8  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  176  ;  for  earlier  instances  of  the  contract 
in  the  Admiralty  records  iee  ibid  i  55  (1536),  92-93  (1541) ;  ii  77  (1573). 

9  Op.  cit.  122-123. 

10  Bensa,  Histoire  du  Contrat  d' Assurance  au  Moyen  Age  (French  tr.)  14-15. 

11  Ashburner,  the  Rhodian  Sea  Law  ccxii-ccxxxiv  ;   VVelwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xiv. 


262  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

has  pointed  out  that  the  pecunia  trajectitia  gave  the  creditor  no  lien 
on  the  ship  or  cargo — indeed  the  borrower  was  not  necessarily  the 
owner  of  either.  The  creditor  had  only  a  general  lien  on  the  goods 
of  the  debtor,  if  this  lien  had  been  expressly  conferred  upon  him.1 
But  gradually  the  practice  grew  up  of  making  the  property  subject 
to  the  risk  primarily  liable  to  pay  the  debt.  This  development 
was  beginning  to  take  place  in  Italy  in  the  thirteenth  century." 
When  it  was  complete,  the  loan  on  bottomry  acquired  its  distin- 
guishing characteristic  of  conferring  upon  the  lender  a  lien  on  the 
ship,  in  addition  to  the  power  to  enforce  payment  from  the  owner 
personally  ; 3  and  the  same  consequences  followed  from  the  contract 
of  respondentia  made  by  the  owner  of  the  cargo,  or  by  the  master 
acting  as  his  agent.4 

A  little  later  a  further  development  took  place,  to  meet  the 
most  usual  case  in  which  the  loan  on  bottomry  or  at  respondentia 
was  made — the  case  where  it  was  made  by  the  master  in  case  of 
necessity.5  Here,  instead  of  giving  rise  to  a  merely  personal  right, 
it  created  a  real  right.  No  personal  liability  was  incurred :  the 
property  over  which  the  lien  is  given  was  solely  liable.6  In  some 
countries  this  species  of  loan  on  bottomry  or  at  respondentia  wholly 
superseded  similar  loans  contracted  by  the  owner  of  ship  or  cargo.7 

Thus  the  contracts  of  bottomry  and  respondentia  assumed  their 
modern  form,  and  fell  apart  from  those  contracts  of  loan  under 
which  money  was  borrowed  (to  be  repaid  on  the  prosperous  ter- 
mination of  the  voyage)  simply  on  the  personal  credit  of  the 
borrower.8  The  former,  as  M.  Bensa  says,  originate,  not  in  the 
classical   Roman  law,  but  in  the  development  of  that  law  which 


1  Bensa,  op.  cit.  14 — "  Le  preteur  ne  jouissait  d'aucune  garantie  sp£ciale  sur  les 
choses  soumises  au  risque,  pr£cisement  parce  que  rien  ne  d^monttait  qu'elles  appar- 
tinssent  a  Femprunteur  ;  il  n'avait  que  droit  de  gage  general  sur  tous  les  biens  presents 
ou  futurs  de  son  debiteur,  et  ce  droit  lui  meme  resultait  dune  clause  de  style  par  laquelle 
le  debiteur  autorisait  le  creancier  a  se  mettre  de  lui  meme  en  possession  des  biens  et  a 
les  vendre  sans  intervention  de  justice." 

2  "  Peu  a  peu  a  l'obligation  generate  du  patrimonie  se  substitua  l'obligation  speciale 
de  l'objet  soumis  au  risque,  et  le  contrat  .  .  .  cr£a  un  droit  r£el  .  .  .  Cette  maniere 
de  contracter  entree  en  usage  au  trezieme  siecle.  se  maintint  pendant  les  siecles  sui- 
vants  avec  des  changements  peu  importants,''  ibid;  cp.  Ashburner,  op.  cit.  ccxxix- 
ccxxxi,  for  instances  of  documents  in  which  there  is  a  special  pledge  of  the  ship,  or  of 
specified  goods,  or  of  all  the  borrower's  goods. 

3  Park,  Marine  Insurances  (1st  ed.)  469. 

4  Ibid  ;  Bensa,  op.  cit.  14-15.  5  Ibid. 

6  Abbott,  Merchant  Shipping  (14th  ed.)  209  ;  Stainbank  v.  Fenning  (1851)  11  C.B. 

5*. 

7  Bensa,  op.  cit.  15-16 — this  happened  at  Barcelona  ;  "  Les  ordonnances  de  1345 
y  prescrivirent  que  le  prestamo  a  ricsgo  de  mar  revetit  la  forme  d'un  acte  public  ou  in- 
terviendraient  la  capitaine  et  l'ecrivain  du  navire  pour  declarer  tous  deux,  sous  la  foi 
du  serment,  que  les  sommes  empruntdes  a  la  grosse  aventure  Pdtaient  r£ellement  par 
suite  de  n6cessit6s  urgentes  .  .  .  toutes  circomstances  qui  devaient  £tre  sp£cific£s 
dans  le  contrat." 

8  Park,  op.  cit.  469,  470. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       263 

took  place  in  the  commercial  cities  of  Italy  in  the  Middle 
Ages.1 

We  have  seen  that  in  all  these  varieties  of  contract  the  lender 
took  the  risks  of  the  voyage ;  but  only  the  risks  of  the  voyage. 
"  Therefore  if  the  money  miscarry  either  before  the  voyage  begun 
or  after  the  term  appointed  for  the  full  loan,  then  the  peril  pertains 
to  the  borrower  thereof  and  not  to  the  lender."2  Similarly,  if  the 
money  were  lost  by  the  negligence  of  the  borrower,  he  must  repay 
it3  The  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty  show  that  at  this  period 
some  of  these  principles,  applicable  to  loans  on  the  personal  credit 
of  the  borrower,  were  applied  also  to  loans  on  bottomry.  In  the 
case  of  Austen  c.  Cattelyn  (1541)4  it  was  contended  that  money 
borrowed  by  the  master  for  the  use  of  the  ship  was  repayable, 
although  the  ship  had  been  lost,  because  (as  the  lenders  alleged) 
she  was  unseaworthy  from  the  start,  and  the  master,  having  dis- 
charged the  greater  part  of  the  cargo,  had  deliberately  cast  away 
the  ship  with  the  rest  of  the  cargo,  in  order  to  avoid  payment  of 
the  loan. 

We  shall  see  that  these  contracts  are  important  in  the  history 
of  the  development  of  the  contract  of  marine  insurance.5  As  late 
as  this  period  the  contracts  of  respondentia  and  insurance  were 
sometimes  combined  in  one  transaction ; 6  and  the  connection 
between  them  has  always  been  intimate  and  obvious."  As  Park 
says,  "  the  lender  on  bottomry  or  at  respondentia  runs  almost  all 
the  same  risks,  with  respect  to  the  property,  on  which  the  loan  is 
made,  that  the  insurer  does  with  respect  to  the  effects  insured."  8 

Average. 

We  have  seen  that  the  laws  of  Oleron  provided  that  when  a 
jettison  was  made  to  save  the  ship,  the  ship  and  cargo,  if  saved, 
must  contribute  to  the  loss.  We  have  seen,  too,  that  the  rules 
laid  down  in  these  laws  were  modified  by  an  ordinance  of  Edward  I., 

1  As  M.  Bensa  has  shown,  op.  cit  11-13,  the  distinguishing  feature  of  these  con- 
tracts, and  their  essential  novelty,  have  been  obscured  by  the  speculations  of  the  jurists 
of  the  fifteenth  and  sixteenth  centuries  and  later,  who  were  intent  upon  proving  that 
they  were  the  same  as  the  pecunia  trajectitia  of  Roman  Law,  and  that  they  were  not 
usurious ;  as  M.  Bensa  says,  at  p.  11,  these  contracts  in  their  modern  form  have  their 
roots  in  the  commercial  customs  of  the  Middle  Ages  ;  it  may  be  noted  that  they  are 
confused  by  Malynes,  op.  cit.  122  ;  but  not  by  Welwod,  Tit.  xiv,  who  in  that  title  only 
deals  with  "  money  lent  to  sea  called  Nauticum  Foenus." 

2  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit,  xiv.  s  iD,d. 

4  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  106-110. 

5  Below  277.  s  Malynes,  op.  cit.  122-123. 

7  Thus  in  Joy  v.  Kent  (1665)  Hardres  418,  to  an  action  on  a  bottomry  bond,  it 
was  pleaded  that  the  rate  of  interest  was  usurious  ;  Hale,  C.B.,  held  that  the  usury 
laws  could  not  apply  ;  he  said,  "  this  is  the  common  way  of  insurance,  and  if  this  was 
void  by  the  statute  of  usury  trade  would  be  destroyed  "  ;  as  we  shall  see,  below  275, 
the  extra  rate  of  interest  is  in  the  nature  of  a  premium  paid  to  the  lender  for  the  risk 
he  runs. 

8  Park,  Marine  Insurances  (1st  ed.)  473. 


264  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

which  provided  that  the  ship  should  lose  the  freight  on  the 
goods  jettisoned,  but  should  not  contribute  to  such  a  loss.1  Dur- 
ing this  period  the  question  what  losses  should  be  considered 
to  be  general  average  losses,  and  what  property  was  liable  to 
contribute  to  such  losses,  was  worked  out  in  some  detail.2 

The  principle  of  the  law  is  contained  in  the  Digest.  "  It  is 
provided  by  the  Rhodian  law  that  if  merchandize  is  thrown 
overboard  to  lighten  the  ship,  the  loss  occasioned  for  the  benefit 
of  all  must  be  made  good  by  all."3  It  was  necessary  that  the 
goods  should  be  deliberately  cast  away  to  ensure  the  safety  of  the 
rest ;  and  so  the  accidental  destruction  of  part  of  the  ship's  gear 
in  a  storm  gave  rise  to  no  such  claim,4  since  it  was  not  deliberately 
destroyed  to  save  the  ship.5  The  writers  of  this  period  repeat  the 
older  rules  as  to  the  necessity  for  a  previous  consultation  before  a 
jettison  was  made ; 6  and  these  rules  lived  on  in  some  continental 
codes.7  As  Abbott  pointed  out,  they  were  not  very  useful  for  the 
purpose  for  which  they  were  invented,  i.e.  to  secure  that  a  jettison 
should  only  be  made  in  a  case  of  real  danger ; 8  and  they  have 
long  ceased  to  be  rules  of  English  law.9 

The  case  of  jettison  was  the  earliest  case  in  which  a  general 
average  contribution  could  be  demanded.  But  the  principle  was 
easily  extended  to  other  cases  where  ship  or  cargo  had  suffered 
for  the  good  of  all.  Thus  Welwod  enumerates  the  cases  of  money 
paid  to  redeem  the  ship  or  goods  from  a  pirate ; 10  damage  occas- 
sioned  to  the  goods  and  the  ship  by  reason  of  a  jettison  ; u  goods 
lost  in  consequence  of  their  being  unladen  into  a  lighter,  for  the 
purpose  of  enabling  the  ship  to  take  refuge  in  harbour,  in  order  to 
avoid  some  danger,  or  to  repair ; 12  and  collision,  where  neither 

1  Vol.  v  123,  124. 

2  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tits,  xvii-xxi ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  109-114  ;  Ridley,  A  view  of 
the  Civil  and  Ecclesiastical  Law  121-124. 

3  Dig.  14.  2. 1. — "  Lege  Rhodia  cavetur,  ut,  si  levandag  navis  gratia  jactus  mercium 
factus  est,  omnium  contributione  sarciatur  quod  pro  omnibus  datum  est." 

4  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xvii. 

5  Dig.  14.  2.  2.  1 — "  si  conservatis  mercibus  deterior  facta  sit  navis  aut  si  quid 
exarmaverit,  nulla  facienda  est  collatio,  quia  dissimilis  earum  rerum  causa  sit,  quae 
navis  gratia  parentur  et  earum,  pro  quibus  mercedem  aliquis  acceperit :  nam  et  si 
faber  incudem  aut  malleum  fregerit,  non  imputaretur  ei  qui  locaverit  opus.  Sed  si 
voluntate  vectorum  vel  propter  aliquem  metum  id  detrimentum  factum  sit,  hoc  ipsum 
sarciri  oportet." 

fi  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xvii ;  Malynes,  op.  cit.  113  ;  vol.  v  123. 

7  Abbott,  op.  cit.  329,  330. 

8  "  Emerigon,  torn,  i  p.  605,  cites  an  observation  of  Targa,  who  says,  that  during 
sixty  years,  in  which  he  had  been  a  magistrate  at  Genoa,  conversant  with  this  subject, 
he  had  known  only  Jive  instances  of  regular  jettison,  all  of  which  were  suspected  of 
fraud,  because  the  forms  had  been  too  well  observed,"  Abbott,  op.  cit.  330  n.  g. 

9  It  may  be  doubted  whether  they  were  part  of  English  law  at  this  period  ;  in  the 
case  of  Whitefeld  c.  Garrarde  (1540)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  95  no  men- 
tion is  made  in  the  pleading  of  any  preliminary  consultation  ;  cp.  Mouse's  Case  (1609) 
12  Co.  Rep.  63. 

10 Tit.  xviii.  "Tit.  xix.  1J Tit.  xx. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       265 

ship  was  in  fault.1  It  was  held  also  in  1575  that,  where  some 
part  of  a  cargo  of  clothes  had  been  taken  by  the  king  of  Denmark 
for  toll,  contribution  must  be  made  by  the  merchants  whose 
clothes  had  not  been  taken.2  But  it  was  laid  down  by  the  House 
of  Lords  in  1698,  in  the  case  of  SJieppard  v.  Wright?  that  no  case 
for  a  general  average  contribution  arose,  unless  it  was  the  loss  of 
the  goods  which  perished  which  contributed  to  the  saving  of  the 
goods  which  were  preserved.  So  that  where  a  ship  was  pursued 
by  enemies  into  a  harbour,  and  there  unloaded  part  of  her  cargo, 
and  then  some  days  after  the  ship  with  the  cargo  left  on  board 
was  captured,  the  cargo  unloaded  was  not  liable  to  contribute  to 
the  loss. 

At  this  period  it  was  settled  that  in  case  of  a  loss  necessary  to 
the  preservation  of  ship  and  goods,  both  ship  and  goods  con- 
tributed.4 In  later  law  the  freight  also  contributed  ; 5  but  it  is  not 
clear  that  this  was  the  rule  at  this  period.  Clothes,  the  personal 
effects  of  passengers,  and  provisions,  did  not  contribute.6  But 
jewels,  articles  of  clothing,  and  other  things  carried  as  cargo  and 
paying  freight,  were  liable  to  contribute.7  At  this  period,  the 
goods  lost  were  reckoned  at  their  cost  price  if  the  loss  occurred 
before  the  middle  of  the  voyage ;  but  at  their  market  price  at  the 
port  of  destination,  if  the  loss  occurred  after  the  middle  of  the 
voyage.8  But  later  English  lawyers  evolved  a  more  logical  rule. 
If  the  ship  gets  to  its  port  of  destination  the  value  is  taken  as  at 
that  place,  on  the  logical  ground  that  "the  person  whose  loss  has 
procured  the  arrival  of  the  ship  at  the  place  of  destination  should 
be  placed  in  the  same  situation  with  those  whose  property  has 
arrived  at  that  place ;  which  can  only  be  done  by  considering  his 
goods  as  having  arrived  there  also."  On  the  other  hand,  if  the 
ship  is  compelled  to  return  to  the  port  from  whence  it  started,  the 
goods  only  contribute  according  to  the  cost  price.9 

At  this  period  the  master  could,  as  under  the  laws  of  Oleron, 
retain  the  cargo  till  the  merchants  liable  had  paid  their  share  of 
the  contribution.10 


1  Tit.  xx  ;  cp.  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (5.S.)  ii  lxxxiv  ;  below  266. 

2  The  Elizabeth,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  39,  40. 

3  Shower  P.C.  18  ;  cp.  House  of  Lords  MSS.  iii  no.  1268 ;  and  this  it  seems  was 
in  accordance  with  the  civil  law  as  applied  in  the  sixteenth  century,  Hicks  v.  Paling- 
ton  (1590)  Moore,  K.B.,  297. 

4  Welwod,  Tit.  xvii.  5  Abbott,  op.  cit.  345. 

6  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xvii ;  the  civil  law  rule  was  otherwise  as  to  clothes  and 
articles  of  personal  adornment,  Dig.  14.  2.  2.  2. 

7  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xvii.  8  Ibid  Tit.  xxi.  9  Abbott,  op.  cit.  347. 
10  Welwod,  op.  cit.  Tit.  xxi — "  The  imposed  taxation,  as  likewise  the  freight,  is 

thought  to  stick  firmly  to  the  said  goods ;  and  therefore  the  master  may  hold  his  hand 
thereon,  until  satisfaction  be  made,  albeit  that  commonly  the  withholding  of  other 
men's  goods  be  not  allowed  "  ;  vol.  v  123. 


2G6  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

Collision. 

We  have  seen  that  the  rules  as  to  collisions  by  sea  contained 
in  the  laws  of  Oleron  were  both  scanty  and  primitive.1  If  one 
ship  intentionally  collided  with  another  ship  at  anchor,  or,  it  would 
seem,  while  under  sail,  the  master  of  the  former  ship  and  the 
merchants  were  liable  to  pay  the  whole  of  the  damage  ;  but  if  the 
collision  occurred  by  accident  or  by  negligence  the  loss  was 
divided  between  the  two  vessels  and  their  cargoes.2 

In  1 815,  in  the  case  of  the  Woodrop  Sims,s  the  law  as  to  the 
incidence  of  liability  for  collision  at  sea  was  summed  up  by  Lord 
Stowell  in  four  rules : — (1)  If  the  collision  was  due  to  the  fault  of 
neither  vessel — if  it  was,  in  other  words,  a  pure  accident — no  legal 
liability  is  imposed  on  the  owners  of  either  vessel  ;  (2)  if  the 
collision  was  due  to  the  fault  of  both  vessels,  the  loss  must  be 
apportioned  equally4  between  the  vessels;  (3)  if  the  collision  is 
due  to  the  fault  of  the  ship  injured  no  legal  liability  arises;  (4)  if 
the  collision  is  due  to  the  fault  of  the  ship  which  has  injured  the 
other,  the  injured  ship  can  recover  full  damages.  It  was  towards 
the  end  of  this  period  that  the  development  of  the  law  was  begin- 
ning which  resulted  in  these  rules.  But  it  was  only  just  beginning, 
as  all  through  the  sixteenth  century  collision  cases  were  very  rare.5 
At  this  period  we  can  only  indicate  some  of  the  remote  causes 
which  shaped  the  law  as  we  know  it  to-day. 

We  have  seen  that  the  rules  laid  down  by  the  laws  of  Oleron 
date  from  a  period  when  the  law,  not  yet  having  attained  to  the 
conception  of  negligence,  could  not  found  liability  upon  it.6  But 
the  civilians  who  practised  in  the  Admiralty  naturally  founded 
liability  upon  dolus  or  culpa.     Therefore  it  became  necessary  both 

1  Vol.  v  122-123. 

2  Laws  of  Oleron  §  15,  Black  Book  of  the  Admiralty  (R.S.)  i  109  ;  Early  Mayor's 
Court  Rolls  223  and  n.  1,  from  which  these  rules  seem  to  have  been  accepted  in  1305. 

3  (1815)  2  Dod.  at  p.. 85 — "  there  are  four  possibilities  under  which  an  accident  of 
this  sort  may  occur.  In  the  first  place,  it  may  happen  without  blame  being  imputable 
to  either  party,  as  when  the  loss  is  occasioned  by  a  storm  or  any  other  vis  major :  in 
that  case  the  misfortune  must  be  borne  by  the  party  on  whom  it  happens  to  light ;  the 
other  not  being  responsible  to  him  in  any  degree.  Secondly,  a  misfortune  of  this  kind 
may  arise  when  both  parties  are  to  blame ;  when  there  has  been  a  want  of  due 
diligence  or  of  skill  on  both  sides  ;  in  such  a  case  the  rule  of  law  is,  that  the  loss  must 
be  apportioned  between  them,  as  having  been  occasioned  by  the  fault  of  both  of  them. 
Thirdly,  it  may  happen  by  the  misconduct  of  the  suffering  party ;  and  then  the  rule 
is,  that  the  sufferer  must  bear  his  own  burden.  Lastly,  it  may  have  been  the  iault  of 
the  ship  which  ran  the  other  down ;  and  in  this  case  the  injured  party  would  be 
entitled  to  an  entire  compensation  from  the  other." 

4  Hay  v.  Le  Neve  (1824)  2  Shaw  Sc.  App.  395 ;  cp.  Stoomvaart  Maatschappy 
Nederland  v.  the  P.  and  O.  Steam  Navigation  Company  (1882)  7  A.C.  at  pp.  818-819 /w 
Lord  Blackburn;  this  rule  lasted  till  1911;  The  Maritime  Conventions  Act  of  that 
year  (1,  2  George  V.  c.  57  §  1,  1)  provides  that  where  both  vessels  are  in  fault  the 
liability  shall  be  "  in  proportion  to  the  degree  in  which  each  vessel  was  in  fault "  ; 
it  is  only  if  it  is  impossible  to  establish  different  degrees  of  fault  that  the  liability  is 
apportioned  equally,  §  1,  1  a. 

6  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxxiii.  6Vol.  v.  122. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       267 

to  reconsider  and  to  supplement  the  rules  contained  in  the  laws  of 
Oleron.  But  the  rarity  of  cases  in  the  sixteenth  century  prevented 
very  much  development  All  the  cases  decided  seem  to  be  cases 
in  which  either  the  defendant  or  the  plaintiff  is  clearly  in  fault.1 
There  could  therefore  be  either  a  clear  condemnation  or  a  clear 
acquittal.  There  is  only  one  case  in  which  a  negligent  master  was 
made  liable  to  pay  half  damages  ;  '2  and  there  were  no  cases  in 
which  neither  or  both  the  ships  were  to  blame.  Welwod's  treat- 
ment of  the  subject  illustrates  the  scantiness  of  the  law.3  He  lays  it 
down  that,  if  a  collision  occur  through  the  fault  of  neither  party,  both 
must  contribute  to  the  loss.4  This  view  of  the  law  seems  to  have 
been  acted  on  at  least  once  in  the  seventeenth  century ; 5  and  it 
passed  into  the  maritime  law  of  some  foreign  states.*5  But  Wel- 
wod  goes  on  to  say  that  this  rule  will  not  apply  if  one  of  the 
ships  perish,  assigning  the  reason  given  by  the  laws  of  Oleron." 
On  the  other  hand,  he  points  out  that  a  negligent  master  may  be 
answerable  to  the  owner  of  his  own  or  of  the  other  ship  by  the 
actio  legis  Aquiliae.  The  liability  which  he  contemplates  seems  to 
have  been  the  liability  of  the  master.  This  is  in  accordance  with 
the  view  that  the  owner  is  not  liable  for  the  master's  negligence ; 8 
and  may  perhaps  partially  account  for  the  paucity  of  cases  on  the 
subject  In  many  cases  the  master  would  not  be  worth  powder 
and  shot 

In  the  seventeenth  century  cases  of  collision  are  more  frequent.9 
Was  it  because  the  lawyers  were  coming  to  the  conclusion  that  the 
exercitor,  or  managing  owner  of  the  ship,  could  be  held  liable  for 
the  negligence  of  the  master  ? 10  Whatever  the  reason,  it  was  clear 
that  a  number  of  new  problems  awaited  the  judges  of  the  court  of 


1  The  plaintiff  recovers  in  the  following  cases : — (1538)  Spysall  c.  Walters, 
Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  70-71 ;  (1539)  Gyllet  c.  Style,  ibid  83  ; 
(1544)  Cocke  c.  Camp,  ibid  133-135  ;  (1546)  Lorde  c.  Butter  ibid  143-145  ;  (1547) 
Darcy  c.  Legg,  ibid  ii  6,  7 ;  the  defendant  got  judgment  in  the  case  of  Daniell  c. 
Nokes(i587)  ibid  ii  167-168,  on  the  ground  that  the  collision  was  due  to  the  plaintiff's 
fault. 

8  (x539)  Handcocke  c.  Payne,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  i  90 — a  case 
settled  by  arbitration. 

3  Op.  cit.  Tit.  xx. 

4"  If  two  ships  rush  and  cross  one  over  another,  and  the  company  swear  their 
innocence,  as  that  it  lay  not  in  their  power  to  stay  the  same,  contribution  must  be 
made  for  one  equal  upset  of  both  their  losses  "  ;  it  should  be  noted  that  Tit.  xx,  in 
which  he  deals  with  collision,  is  entitled  "  Of  contribution  for  lightening  and  dis- 
burdening of  ships  for  their  easier  entry  to  the  port,  and  for  other  chances  " ;  cp. 
Godolphin,  Admiralty  Jurisdiction,  Introd. 

5  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxxiv — a  case  of  1647. 

'  Abbott,  op.  cit  342 — as  he  says,  in  England  in  such  a  case,  the  owners  of  ship 
and  cargo  bear  their  own  loss  ;  such  a  misfortune  was  a  peril  of  the  sea ;  and  in  this 
English  law  agrees  with  the  classical  Roman  Law,  Dig.  9.  2.  29.  3. 

7  Vol.  v  122  n.  10. 

8  Above  252.  'Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  Ixxxiii. 
10  Above  252  nn.  6  and  7. 


268  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

Admiralty.  If  the  injured  vessel  or  the  injuring  vessel  was  alone 
to  blame  the  law  was  plain  enough.  But  what  was  to  happen  if 
neither  was  to  blame,  or  if  both  were  to  blame,  or  if  the  cause  of 
the  collision  was  not  clearly  ascertainable  ?  In  all  these  cases  the 
court  seems  to  have  gone  on  the  principle  of  dividing  the  loss 
between  the  two  ships  ; x  and  Mr.  Marsden  points  out  that  at  this 
period  the  Dutch  lawyers  were  also  beginning  to  follow  a  similar 
rule.2  The  final  settlement  of  the  sphere  of  this  rule— this  judicium 
rusticum  as  it  has  sometimes  been  derisively  called — belongs  to 
the  eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  century. 

We  have  seen  that  the  Admiralty  lawyers,  being  civilians, 
naturally  grounded  liability  upon  dolus  or  culpa ;  and  the  logical 
consequence  of  this  conception  is  the  modern  application  of  the 
rule  of  the  division  of  loss  to  the  case  where  both  ships  are  at 
fault.  When  the  common  law  came  to  found  civil  liability  upon 
negligence  or  wrongful  intent,3  the  principles  which  it  applied 
to  the  cases  of  collision  which  fell  within  its  jurisdiction,4  did 
not  materially  differ  from  the  principles  applied  by  the  court  of 
Admiralty  as  laid  down  in  the  Woodrop  Sims}  The  one  great 
difference  was  between  the  common  law  rule  of  contributory 
negligence,  and  the  Admiralty  rule  as  to  division  of  loss.6  And, 
whatever  may  be  the  comparative  merits  of  these  two  opposing 
rules  from  the  point  of  view  of  practical  utility,7  it  can  hardly  be 
denied  that,  if  liability  for  wrong  is  to  be  founded  upon  dolus  or 
culpa,  the  Admiralty  rule  is  the  more  logical  of  the  two.8     The 

1  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxxiii-lxxxv  ;  Marsden,  Collisions  at  Sea, 
note  to  Chap.  vi. 

2  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  lxxxv,  citing  Neostadius  who  says,  "  curia, 
cum  de  culpa  authore  non  constat,  vel  quod  utrobique  culpa  par  erat,  damnun  commune 
ad  utrumque  spectare  censuit,  condemnavitque  reum  ut  damni  semissem  praestaret, 
sententiae  executione  in  ipsam  navem  dirigenda  mercesque  sequestratas." 

3  Below  447-459. 

4  The  common  law  courts  had  exclusive  jurisdiction  over  claims  for  damage 
suffered  or  committed  by  a  ship  within  the  body  of  a  county ;  and  the  court  of 
Admiralty  was  given  a  concurrent  jurisdiction  by  3,  4  Victoria  c.  65  §  6,  and  24 
Victoria  c.  10  §  7. 

5Cayzer  v.  Carron  Company  (1884)  9  A.C.  at  pp.  880-8S1  per  Lord  Blackburn. 

6  The  Judicature  Act  1873,  36,  37  Victoria  c.  66  §  25.  9  enacted  that,  for  the  future, 
the  Admiralty  rule  was  to  prevad  in  all  cases  of  collision  between  two  ships. 

7  See  Marsden,  Collisions  at  Sea  122,  for  a  discussion  of  this  question — as  he  says, 
the  Admiralty  rule  "  prevents  the  innocent  owner  of  cargo  on  board  either  ship  from 
recovering  from  the  wrong-doing  owner  of  either  ship  more  than  half  his  loss  :  and  it 
works  in  a  very  arbitrary  and  uncertain  manner  when  combined  with  the  statutory 
limitation  of  liability." 

8 In  The  Bernina  (2)  (1887)  12  P.D.  at  p.  89  Lindley,  L.J.,  points  out  that,  in  a 
case  where  the  damage  has  been  suffered  by  the  combined  negligence  of  the  plaintiff 
and  defendant,  the  Admiralty  rule  as  to  the  apportionment  of  damages  is  the  more 
logical ;  cp.  L.  R.  Scott,  Collisions  at  Sea  where  both  Ships  are  in  Fault,  L.Q.R.  xiii  at 
p.  20 — "  The  Admiralty  rule  is  really  an  advance  upon  the  common  law  rule  in  the 
direction  of  apportionment  according  to  blame  "  ;  we  may  regard  the  rule  laid  down 
in  the  Maritime  Conventions  Act  1911,  above  266  n.  4,  as  a  still  further  advance  in 
the  same  direction. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       269 

common  law  rule  is,  as  we  have  seen,1  the  logical  result  of  the 
mediaeval  principle  of  founding  civil  liability,  not  upon  negligence, 
but  upon  an  act  which  causes  damage — if  the  act  which  was  the 
immediate  cause  of  the  damage  was  that  of  the  plaintiff  he  cannot 
recover.  The  common  law  rule  dates  from  a  period  before  the 
idea  of  negligence,  as  one  of  the  foundations  of  civil  liability,  had 
been  acclimatized  in  the  common  law ;  and  though  it  may  have 
its  merits  as  a  rule  of  practical  utility,  neither  its  name  nor  its 
contents  altogether  harmonize  with  modern  foundations  upon 
which  civil  liability  is  now  usually  based. 

Salvage. 

That  those  who  rescued  persons  or  property  from  the  perils  of 
the  sea  should  be  rewarded,  is  a  principle  recognized  from  the 
earliest  times.2  But  right  down  to  this  period  the  rules  of  law 
on  this  subject  are  scanty,  and,  to  a  large  extent,  turn  upon  the 
character  of  the  cases  in  which  the  claims  arose.3  In  the  case  of 
goods  wrecked  or  derelict,  early  statutes  provided  that,  if  man  or 
beast  escaped,  the  owner  should  have  them,  if  he  claimed  within  a 
year  and  a  day.4  Such  goods,  if  unclaimed,  belonged  to  the  crown, 
and  later  to  the  Admiral,  as  Admiralty  droits,  unless  the  privilege 
of  taking  them  had  been  granted  as  a  franchise  to  an  individual  or 
a  corporation.5  But  those  who  had  salved  them  were  entitled  to 
a  reward,6  the  amount  of  which  seems  to  have  been  quite  uncertain, 
though  it  was  usually  considered  that  the  salvor  should  have  half.7 
In  the  case  of  goods  recaptured  from  the  enemy  the  amount  to  be 
awarded  was  in  the  discretion  of  the  court.8  In  the  case  of  a  ship 
in  distress,  which  was  not  technically  a  wreck,  the  reward  of  the 
salvors  seems  to  have  been  treated  sometimes  as  depending  upon 
the  bargain  made,9  sometimes  as  a  matter  to  be  determined  by 
the  court.10     The  law  was  therefore  in  a  confused  state.      It  is  clear 

1  Vol.  iii  37S-379.  382  ;  below  459-462.  2  Vol.  v  85. 

'Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  xxxii-xxxix. 

4  3  Edward  I.  c.  14  ;  4  Edward  I.  c.  14. 

5  On  the  whole  subject  of  the  early  law  of  wreck  see  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty 
(S.S.)  ii  xxxix-xli ;  vol.  i  560-561. 

*27  Edward  III.  st.  2  c.  13 — goods  which  cannot  be  called  wreck  are  to  be  re- 
stored to  their  owners,  who  are  to  pay  those  who  have  salved  them  the  amount 
assessed  by  sheriffs  or  other  local  officials  with  the  advice  and  consent  of  four  or  six 
"dez  meillours  et  plus  suffisauntes  prodehomes  du  pays." 

7 1"  1333  half  was  alleged  to  be  due  by  custom,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty 
(S.S.)  i.  xxvi ;  in  a  writ  to  the  justices  in  1377  to  try  a  case  of  wreck,  there  is  a  direction 
that  a  proper  reward  be  paid  to  the  salvors,  ibid  i  xliv ;  in  Henry  VIII.'s  reign  half 
was  awarded  to  the  salvors  of  a  ship,  ibid  i  lxx ;  in  Maye  c.  Hawkyns  (1573)  ibid  ii 
149  there  is  a  decree  for  ^938  out  of  a  total  value  of  £1150. 

8  Saunderson  c.  Richardson  (1546-1547)  ibid  i  146-148;  Richardson  c.  Saunderson 
(*553)  ibid  ii  87-88 ;  in  the  latter  case  there  is  an  allegation  that  by  law  only  £5  was 
due  in  such  cases ;  but  the  court  evidently  did  not  consider  that  this  was  the  law. 

9  Ibid  ii  xxxiii ;  Home  c.  Delapyn  (1538-1539)  ibid  i  66-67. 

10  Maye  c.  Hawkyns  (1573)  ibid  ii  149. 


270  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

that  the  amount  which  could  be  fairly  claimed  must  to  a  large 
extent  depend  upon  the  circumstances  of  the  particular  case. 
Therefore,  in  the  course  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  practice 
grew  up  of  allowing  the  court  in  all  cases  to  assess  the  amount 
due,  upon  proper  proceedings  being  instituted  for  this  purpose. 
The  first  case  in  which  this  occurred  was  in  1633.1  It  was  a  case 
in  which  proceedings  had  been  taken  to  have  a  ship  condemned 
as  a  wreck.  "  The  owners  and  salvors  intervened  '  pro  eorum 
interesse,'  and  the  salvors  claimed  a  moiety  of  the  property,  'or  a 
verie  good  and  sufficient  reward,'  as  due  to  them  by  custom.  This 
was  the  common  form  of  a  salvage  action  throughout  the  seventeenth 
and  eighteenth  centuries."  If  the  salvage  service  were  performed 
on  land  the  common  law  courts  prevented  the  court  of  Admiralty 
from  assuming  jurisdiction.  But  they  applied  a  similar  rule.  The 
salvor  could  retain  possession  of  the  goods  until  a  proper  com- 
pensation was  made ;  and,  if  the  parties  could  not  agree  to  the 
amount,  a  jury  could  assess  it  on  proper  proceedings  being  taken.2 

The  Maritime  Lien. 

At  the  present  day  many  of  the  incidents  of  the  contract  of 
carriage  by  sea  result  in  the  creation  of  a  maritime  lien.  The 
maritime  lien  has  been  defined  as  "  a  privileged  claim  upon  a 
thing  in  respect  of  service  done  to  it  or  injury  caused  by  it,  to  be 
carried  into  effect  by  legal  process." 3  Thus  it  is  "  a  right 
acquired  by  one  over  a  thing  belonging  to  another — a  jus  in  re 
aliena.  It  is,  so  to  speak,  a  subtraction  from  the  absolute  property 
of  the  owner  in  the  thing.  This  right  must,  therefore,  in  some 
way  have  been  derived  from  the  owner,  either  directly,  or  through 
the  acts  of  persons  deriving  their  authority  from  the  owner.  The 
person  who  has  acquired  the  right  cannot  be  deprived  of  it  by 
alienation  of  the  thing  by  the  owner.  It  does  not  follow  that  a 
right  to  a  personal  claim  against  the  owner  of  the  res  always 
coexists  with  a  right  against  the  res.  The  right  against  the  res 
may  be  conferred  on  such  terms,  or  in  such  circumstances,  that  a 
person  acquiring  that  right  obtains  the  security  of  the  res  alone, 
and  no  rights  against  the  owner  thereof  personally.  A  simple 
illustration  of  this  is  the  case  of  bottomry."4  The  chief  cases  in 
which  a  maritime  lien  arises  at  the  present  day  are  the  cases  of 
bottomry,  salvage,  wages,  masters'  wages  disbursements  and 
liabilities,5  and  damage.     Thus  it  appears  that  at  the  present  day 

1  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  xxxvi-xxxvii. 

2  Abbott,  op.  cit.  383-384. 

3  The  Ripon  City  [1897]  P.  at  pp.  241-242  per  Gorell  Barnes,  J. 

4  Ibid  at  pp.  242-243. 

5  The  lien  for  masters'  wages  disbursements  and  liabilities  was  given  by  57,  58 
Victoria  c.  60  §  167,  1  and  2. 


THE  CONTRACT  OF  CARRIAGE       271 

a  maritime  lien  can  arise  either  ex  contractu  or  quasi  ex  contractu 
or  ex  delicto. 

These  maritime  liens  differ  wholly  from  common  law  liens, 
because  they  are  not  dependent  upon  the  continued  possession  by 
the  lienor  of  the  property  subject  to  the  lien ; 1  and  they  differ 
also  in  some  respects  from  equitable  liens.2  The  question  arises, 
How  did  they  originate?  On  this  question  different  theories 
have  been  advanced  ;  and  probably  different  theories  may  be  true 
in  respect  of  the  very  different  kinds  of  maritime  lien  recognized 
by  modern  law.  It  is  clear,  at  any  rate,  that  we  must,  in  discus- 
sing this  question,  distinguish  between  the  liens  which  arise  from 
contract  or  quasi  contract,  and  those  which  arise  from  delict. 

We  must  probably  look  to  an  application  of  the  Roman  law 
of  hypothec  for  the  origins  of  the  contractual  or  quasi  contractual 
liens.3  The  civil  law  recognized  that  a  person  who  repaired  or 
fitted  out  a  ship  was  a  privileged  creditor ; 4  and  from  this  it  is  no 
long  step  to  take  to  say  that  such  a  person  had  a  tacit  hypothec 
on  the  property  fitted  out  or  repaired.  Probably  also  this 
development  was  helped  forward  by  the  ordinary  form  of 
Admiralty  process,  under  which  the  ship  was  arrested.  But  of 
this  I  shall  speak  a  little  later.5  At  any  rate,  in  the  sixteenth 
century,  we  find  such  a  lien  existing  by  express  agreement  in  the 
case  of  bottomry,6  and  by  implication  of  law  in  the  case  of  non- 
payment of  money  due  for  repairs,7  and  perhaps  in  the  case  of 
non-payment  of  wages  ; 8  and  in  the  seventeenth  century  a  similar 
lien  was  recognized  in  the  case  of  salvage  services. 9 

It  is  not  probable  that  the  lien  which  arises  from  damage  (such 
as  collision)  arose  from  an  adaptation  of  the  principle  of  hypothec. 
In  some  continental  laws,  it  is  true,  it  may  have  had  this  origin.10 

1 "  A  maritime  lien  does  not  include  or  require  possession.  The  word  is  used  in 
maritime  law,  not  in  the  strict  legal  sense  in  which  we  understand  it  in  courts  of 
common  law.  in  which  case  there  could  be  no  lien  where  there  was  no  possession 
actual  or  constructive ;  but  to  express,  as  if  by  analogy,  the  nature  of  claims  which 
neither  presuppose  nor  require  possession.  This  was  well  understood  in  the  civil  law, 
by  which  there  might  be  a  pledge  with  possession  and  a  hypothecation  without  pos- 
session, and  by  which  in  certain  cases  the  right  travelled  with  the  thing  into  whosoever 
possession  it  came,"  The  Bold  Buccleugh  (1850-1851)  7  Moo.  P.C.  at  p.  284  ;  vol.  vii 
5II-5I3. 

2  Ibid  513. 

3  Gorell  Barnes,  J.,  in  the  Ripon  City  [1897]  P.  at  p.  239,  seems  to  favour  this 
view. 

4  Dig-  42-  5-  26 — "  qui  in  navem  exstruendam  vel  instruendam  credidit  vel  etiam 
emendam,  privilegium  habet  "  ;  see  also  ibid  42.  5.  34 ;  and  20.  4.  5. 

5  Below  272.  «  Above  262.  7  Above  n.  4,  262. 

8  In  the  sixteenth  century  there  appears  to  be  very  little  evidence  of  a  maritime 
lien  for  wages,  see  e.g.  Tye  c.  Spryngham  (1561)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.) 
ii  122-123— a  personal  action  ;  cp.  ibid  131-132  in  a  suit  of  1565,  against  a  ship  and  the 
owner,  it  appears  the  ship  was  arrested  because  the  mariners  were  unable  otherwise  to 
recover  their  wages  from  the  owner ;  in  1597,  ibid  ii  lxxiv  (no.  69),  there  is  a  decree 
against  the  ship  for  wages,  necessaries,  debts,  and  bottomry. 

9  Ibid  ii  xxxvi-xxxvii.  10  See  Abbott,  op.  cit.  (14th  ed.)  ion  n.  b. 


272  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

But  we  do  not  find  this  development  in  English  law.  Two  very 
different  views  have  been  put  forward  on  this  matter.  Mr.  Justice 
Holmes  regards  it  as  a  surviving  form  of  noxal  liability,  which 
must  be  attributed  to  the  same  set  of  legal  ideas  as  those  in  which 
the  deodand  originated.1  But  there  are  several  objections  to  this 
view.  In  the  first  place,  very  slight  traces  of  the  existence  of 
such  a  lien  appear  in  the  early  records 2 — in  fact  its  existence  was 
not  finally  established  till  1850-1851.3  But  if  we  are  to  seek  its 
origin  in  these  primitive  notions  as  to  noxal  liability,  it  is  precisely 
in  the  early  records  that  we  should  expect  to  find  it  prominent. 
In  the  second  place,  it  is  not  very  likely  that  primitive  ideas  of 
this  kind  would  be  found  in  a  court,  the  law  and  practice  of  which 
were  moulded  on  the  civil  law.  In  the  third  place,  it  was  an  idea 
which  ran  counter  to  the  older  opinion  that  the  owner  was  not 
liable  for  the  torts  of  the  master  and  crew.4  Even  as  late  as  1802 
it  was  argued  that  the  "torts  of  the  master  cannot  be  supposed  to 
hypothecate  the  ship,  nor  to  produce  any  lien  on  it."5  On  these 
grounds  the  rival  view  put  forward  by  Mr.  Marsden  seems  to  be 
preferable.  His  view  is  that  this  lien  arose  from  an  inference 
drawn  from  the  Admiralty  process  of  arresting  the  ship  in  order 
to  compel  payment.6  But  it  may  be  said,  if  this  is  so,  we  might 
expect  this  lien  to  have  arisen  very  much  earlier  than  it  actually 
appears.  The  answer  to  this  objection  appears  to  be  as  follows  : — 
In  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries  the  common  law 
courts  prevented  the  court  of  Admiralty  from  excercising  juris- 
diction over  individuals  personally  ;  but  they  did  not  prevent 
the  court  from  exercising  its  jurisdiction  over  a  thing  hypothe- 
cated or  subject  to  a  lien.7  In  this  period  the  court  claimed 
to  exercise  both  these  kinds  of  jurisdiction.  As  often  as  not 
the  arrest  of  the  res  was  mere  process  to  compel  appearance — 
alternative  to  an  arrest  of  the  person.8  But  when  the  court  was 
prohibited  from  exercising  this  personal  jurisdiction,  the  actio  in 

1  The  Common  Law  25-27. 

2  Marsden,  Collisions  at  Sea  (6th  ed.)  70-71 ;  one  such  case  is  to  be  found  in  Anon. 
(1661)  1  Keble  44. 

3  The  Bold  Buccleugh  (1850- 185 1)  7  Moo.  P.C.  267  ;  cp.  The  Ripon  City  [1897]  p- 
at  p.  241 ;  The  Veritas  [1901]  P.  at  p.  310. 

4  Above  252. 

5  Browne,  Civil  Law  (2nd  ed.)  ii  140  cited  by  Gorell  Barnes,  J.,  in  The  Veritas 
[igoi]  P.  at  p.  310. 

6  Collisions  at  Sea  70-71 — "  there  are  to  be  found  in  the  books  cases  which  give 
some  countenance  to  the  doctrine  that  in  Admiralty  the  ship  is  the  real  defendant ;  that 
the  ship  is  sued  because  it  is  she  that  has  done  the  wrong,  and  she  that  pays  the 
recompence.  But  it  is  submitted  that  this  view  of  the  liability  of  the  ship  in  Admiralty 
is  not  well  founded.  .  .  .  The  process  of  Admiralty  courts  against  the  ship  seems 
clearly  to  have  originated,  not  in  any  such  idea  as  that  involved  in  the'law  of  deodand, 
or  in  the  noxal  action  of  the  civil  law,  but  simply  as  a  ready  and  effectual  means  of 
compelling  the  wrongdoer  to  appear  and  defend  the  action  or  to  make  recompence." 

7  The  Dictator  [1892]  P.  at  pp.  310-311  per  Jeune,  J.  8  Ibid  311-313. 


INSURANCE  273 

rem,  founded  on  the  arrest  of  a  res,  came  into  greater  prominence. ! 
By  an  inversion  of  cause  and  effect  not  uncommon  in  legal  history, 
it  came  to  be  thought  that,  whenever  a  res  could  be  arrested  in 
order  that  a  claim  might  be  asserted  against  its  owner,  a  lien  over 
that  res  existed.  This  seems  to  have  been  the  line  of  reasoning 
used  by  the  court  in  the  case  of  The  Bold  Buccleugh,  which 
finally  established  the  existence  of  this  lien.2 

At  this  period,  therefore,  the  modern  law  as  to  maritime  liens 
is  still  very  remote.  We  see  one  root  of  it  in  the  liens  which 
arise  by  contract  express  or  implied.  But  the  other  root — the 
prominence  given  to  the  Admiralty  jurisdiction  in  rem  by  the 
prohibition  of  its  personal  jurisdiction,  and  the  inference  drawn 
from  that  prominence — are  as  yet  in  the  future. 


Ill 

Insurance 

In  modern  law  insurance  would  not  form  merely  a  section  of 
a  chapter  on  the  Law  Merchant.  The  contract  to  which  we  look 
to  save  us  harmless  not  only  from  the  risks  incident  to  life  itself, 
but  also  from  the  risks  incident  to  the  various  business  and  social 
activities  of  life  in  a  civilized  society,  and  to  the  obligations  which 
a  paternal  government  places  upon  the  most  deserving  of  its  sub- 
jects, would  certainly  demand  and  deserve  a  chapter  to  itself.  On 
the  other  hand,  if  we  look  at  insurance  only  from  the  point  of  view 
of  its  origins,  we  should  not  give  it  even  a  section  to  itself,  but 
should  class  it  simply  as  one  of  the  topics  of  maritime  law.  I 
shall  adopt  neither  of  these  methods.  Remembering  the  important 
place  which  this  contract  was  beginning  to  fill  even  in  this  period, 
I  shall  treat  it  as  a  separate  topic ;  and,  remembering  that  we 
must  look  for  its  origins,  and  for  the  earliest  and  most  important 
sphere  of  its  application  to  maritime  law,  I  shall  treat  it  as  a  topic 
which  belongs  peculiarly  to  the  Law  Merchant.  In  this  section 
I  shall  deal,  firstly,  with  the  origins  of  the  contract  of  marine  in- 
surance ;  secondly,  with  the  beginnings  of  the  development  of  this 
form  of  insurance  in  English  Law  ;  and,  thirdly,  with  the  origins  of 
other  forms  of  insurance. 


1  The  Dictator  [1892]  P.  at  p.  313  per  Jeune,  J. 

2  "  A  maritime  lien  is  the  foundation  of  the  proceeding  in  rem  .  .  .  and  whilst  it 
must  be  admitted  that  where  such  a  lien  exists,  a  proceeding  in  rem  may  be  had,  it 
will  be  found  to  be  equally  true  that  in  all  cases  where  a  proceeding  in  rem  is  the 
proper  course,  then  a  maritime  lien  exists,"  7  Moo.,  P.C.,  at  p.  2S4  ;  as  Gorell 
Barnes,  J.,  points  out  in  The  Veritas  [1901]  P.  at  p.  310  this  reasoning  is  not  strictly 
true,  as  there  may  be  rights  to  proceed  in  rem  though  no  maritime  lien  exists. 

VOL.  VIII.— 18 


274  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

The  Origin  of  the  Contract  of  Marine  Insurance 

Insurance  has  been  defined  l  as  a  contract  by  which  one  party 
(the  insurer)  in  consideration  of  a  premium,  undertakes  to  in- 
demnify another  (the  insured)  against  loss.  The  researches  of 
M.  Bensa 2  have  proved  that  the  earliest  variety  of  this  contract 
was  the  contract  of  marine  insurance  ;  that  as  a  separate  and  in- 
dependent contract  it  dates  from  the  early  years  of  the  fourteenth 
century ;  and  that  it  was  evolved,  like  many  other  of  our  modern 
mercantile  institutions,  in  the  commercial  cities  of  Italy.3  As 
M.  Lefort  has  said,  this  contract  was  not  devised  by  a  legislator.  It 
was  the  last  term  in  the  evolution  of  various  legal  devices  invented 
to  provide  against  the  risks  of  the  sea ; 4  and  though  there  is  no 
evidence  of  the  existence  of  an  independent  contract  of  insurance 
before  the  beginning  of  the  fourteenth  century,  we  can  see  in  these 
various  devices  the  germs  from  which  this  contract  was  evolved. 
And,  even  when  in  practice  it  had  come  to  be  recognized  as  a 
distinct  species  of  contract,  it  still  continued  to  be  disguised  under 
the  forms  of  a  sale,  an  exchange,  or  a  maritime  loan,  in  order  to 
prevent  any  question  whether  it  was  illegal  on  the  ground  that  it 
infringed  the  laws  against  usury.0 

Among  both  the  Greeks  and  the  Romans  we  meet  with  stip- 
ulations, accessory  to  the  contract  of  carriage,  which  settled  the 
incidence  of  the  risk  of  loss  of,  or  damage  to,  the  goods  carried.0 
For  instance,  either  the  carrier 7  or  the  consignee  8  might  guarantee 

1  Smith,  Mercantile  Law  (nth  ed.)  451. 

2  "  II  contrato  di  assicurazione  nel  medio  evo  ;  studi  e  ricerche  (1894)" ;  I  cite  from 
the  French  translation,  Histoire  du  Contrat  d'Assurance  au  Moyen  Age,  traduit  par 
Valery,  Introduction  par  Lefort  (1897) ;  Vance,  Insurance  Law,  Essays  in  Anglo- 
American  Legal  Hist,  iii  104-108,  gives  some  account  of  M.  Bensa's  conclusions. 

8  Bensa,  op.  cit.  18-24. 

4  '•  Le  contrat  d' assurance  maritime  n'est  pas  du  au  genie  d'un  legislateur  ;  c'est 
le  dernier  terme  d'une  serie  devolutions  par  lesquelles  s'est  manifestee  l'idee  de  pr£- 
voyance  dans  la  lutte  contre  les  fortunes  de  mer,  lutte  qui  devait  erte  d'autant  plus 
vive  que  de  jour  en  jour  augmentait  l'importance  des  vies  et  des  int^rets  confi^s  aux 
caprices  des  flots,"  op.  cit.  Introd.  vi. 

6  Petrus  Santerna,  De  Assecurationibus  Pt.  I.  §§  4-6  (Tractatus  Universi  Juris  vi 
Pt.  I.  348b),  cites  and  refutes  various  authors  who  had  held  insurance  contracts  void  on 
this  ground ;  as  he  says,  §  6,  "  susceptio  periculi  simpliciter  non  facit  conventionem 
illicitam  nisi  alias  sic  illicita  "  ;  and  he  argues,  §§  10-16,  that  even  a  loan  of  money  to 
X,  who  pays  a  premium  to  the  lender  to  insure  it,  is  not  usury. 

6  For  some  account  of  these  arrangements  see  Vance,  op.  cit.  99-103;  Lefort,  op. 
cit.  vii ;  Ashburner,  The  Rhodian  Sea  Law,  ccxii-ccxxi,  gives  the  fullest  account  of  the 
maritime  loans  at  Greece  and  Rome,  which  are  the  direct  ancestors  of  the  insurance 
contract. 

7  Thus  Cicero  states,  Epist.  ad  Fam.  II.  Epist.  17  (cited  Vance,  op.  cit.  99)  that 
the  government  should  not  bear  the  risks  of  the  transportation  of  certain  public  money 
from  Laodicea — "  Laodicete  me  praedes  accepturum  arbitror  omnis  pecuniae  public??, 
ut  et  mihi  et  populo  cautum  sit  sine  vecturae  periculo." 

8  Suetonius  states  that  Claudius  assumed  the  risks  of  corn  transported  to  Rome, 
Life  of  Claudius  V.  c.  18  (cited  Vance,  op.  cit.  99)—"  Nam  et  negotiatoribus  certa  lucra 
proposuit,  suscepto  in  se  damno  si  cui  quid  per  tempestates  accidisset." 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     275 

the  safe  arrival  of  the  goods  carried.  The  maritime  loan — 
pecunia  trajectitia — can  be  analysed  into  a  contract  oi  mutuum  with 
a  contract  of  insurance  added  to  it x  ;  for  the  higher  interest  paid  by 
the  borrower  represented  a  premium,  in  consideration  of  which  he 
was  not  liable  to  pay  if  the  ship  were  lost.  Then  again  we  meet, 
in  the  earlier  mediaeval  period,  mutual  associations  formed  to 
guard  against  certain  risks  of  the  sea,  as  for  instance  against  the 
risks  which  arose  from  the  issue  of  letters  of  marque,  or  from  the 
practice  of  reprisals ;  -  and  at  Genoa  there  was  established  an  in- 
stitution— the  Officium  Robarie — to  give  redress  against  Genoese 
citizens  who  had  committed  acts  of  piracy  against  any  trader, 
which  really  gave  a  sort  of  state  insurance  against  this  particular 
risk.3 

More  immediately  connected  with  the  development  of  the  con- 
tract of  insurance  were  the  stipulations  as  to  risk,  introduced  into 
the  ordinary  commercial  contracts  of  the  thirteenth  century.  In- 
deed, M.  Valery  thinks  that,  in  the  thirteenth  century,  some  of 
these  contracts,  e.g.  contracts  of  sale  or  loan,  were  never  intended 
to  be  sales  or  loans,  but  insurances.4  Thus  in  the  contract  of 
" commenda"  under  which  A  advances  money  or  other  property  to 
B  to  trade  with,  there  is  usually  a  stipulation  as  to  the  party  on 
whom  the  risk  of  accidental  loss  is  to  fall.5  In  the  contract  of 
mutuum  it  is  probable  that,  though  it  evaded  the  canonical  pro- 
hibition of  usury  by  calling  itself  mutuum  "gratis  et  amore,"  6  the 
lender  often  paid  over  the  money  advanced  with  a  deduction,  in 
consideration  that  nothing  should  be  payable  if  the  money  were 
lost  by  accident ;  and  such  a  deduction  is,  as  M.  Bensa  has  said, 
a  true  premium  of  insurance. "  Similarly,  contracts  of  sale  or  ex- 
change {cambium)  were  used  to  disguise  transactions  intended  to 
operate  as  loans  at  sufficient  interest  to  compensate  the  lender, 

1  Above  261 ;  Lefort,  op.  cit.  vii ;  cp.  Ashburner,  op.  cit.  ccxvi,  ccxvii ;  Dig. 
22.  2.  1.  thus  defines  pecunia  trajectitia — "  trajectitia  ea  pecunia  est  quae  trans  mare 
vehitur  .  .  .  Sed  videndum  an  merces  ex  ea  pecunia  comparatae  in  ea  causa  habentur  ? 
et  interest,  utrum  etiam  ipsa?  periculo  creditoris  navigent :  tunc  enim  trajectitia  pecunia 
fit." 

2  Lefort,  op.  cit  vii  n.  4.  3  Ibid  3. 

4  Contrats  d'Assurance  Maritime  du  XHIe  Siecle  (1916),  in  which  he  analyses 
certain  documents  printed  by  Blancard,  Documents  in6dits  sur  le  commerce  de 
Marseille. 

5  Bensa,  op.  cit.  2 — "  les  clauses  relatives  aux  risques  figurent  de  tres  bonne  heure 
dans  les  contrats  de  commande,  car  on  concoit  aisement  l'mteret  du  commandite  a 
s'affranchir  de  route  responsabilite  a  raison  des  cas  fortuits  dont  pouvaient  avoir  a 
soufTrir  les  marchandises  qui  lui  etaient  confiees  "  ;  for  this  contract  see  above  195-197. 

6  Bensa,  op.  cit.  3. 

7  Ibid  3,  4 — he  conjectures  that  "  les  integers  etaient  preleves  des  le  moment  de 
la  formation  du  contrat  sur  la  somme  pretee,  exactement  comme  cela  se  pratique 
encore  aujourdhui  pour  l'escompte  des  effets  de  commerce.  S'il  etait  possible  de 
demontrer  la  verite  de  cette  conjecture,  il  faudrait  voir  dans  cette  retenue  operee 
au  profit  du  preteur,  le  payement  d'une  prime  d'assurance  en  retour  de  laquelle  il 
assumait  les  risques  du  pret." 


276  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

both  for  the  use  of  his  money,  and  for  the  provision  that  nothing 
was  to  be  payable  if  the  money  were  accidentally  lost.1  The  form 
of  a  contract  of  sale  was  adapted  to  this  purpose  as  follows  :  "  In- 
stead of  B  buying  goods  with  money  lent  by  A,  A  buys  the  goods 
himself  and  sells  them  to  B,  and  the  price  which  B  agrees  to  pay 
will  be  (a)  payable  at  a  future  date ;  (b)  contingent  upon  the  safe 
arrival  at  the  place  of  payment,  either  of  the  original  goods  or  the 
goods  into  which  they  have  been  converted ;  and  (c)  sufficient  to 
meet  the  sum  paid  by  A  with  maritime  interest  Similarly  in  the 
case  of  exchange,  B  received  coins  from  A  on  the  terms  of  paying 
different  coins  (which  would  be  of  a  different  value)  at  another 
time  or  place ;  and  according  as  the  coins  were  at  the  risk  of  the 
borrower  or  lender,  the  value  of  the  coins  to  be  returned  would 
differ.'2  The  difference  between  the  rates  of  exchange,  according 
as  the  money  was  repayable  in  any  event,  or  only  on  the  pros- 
perous termination  of  the  voyage,  represents  again  a  premium  of 
insurance.3  As  M.  Bensa  has  said,4  it  is  only  necessary  to  split 
up  such  arrangements  into  their  component  parts  in  order  to 
arrive  at  the  idea  of  an  independent  contract  of  insurance.  "  It 
would  only  be  necessary  for  a  third  person  to  intervene  between 
a  purchaser  who  intended  to  purchase  goods  arrived  safely,  and  a 
vendor  who  wished  to  throw  on  the  purchaser  the  risks  of  the 
sea,  and  to  offer  to  take  these  risks  for  the  sum  which  the  course 
of  trade  and  the  rate  of  exchange  had  fixed  as  the  difference  in 
the  price,  according  as  one  or  other  party  took  these  risks."5 

In  1 347  we  have  in  the  archives  of  Genoa  what  is  perhaps  the 
oldest  contract  of  insurance  ;  and  the  archives  of  Florence  show  that, 
in  the  first  twenty  years  of  the  fourteenth  century,  it  was  an 
ordinary  commercial  transaction  in  the  commercial  towns  of  Italy.6 
But,  as  we  have  seen,  the  contracts  in  which  the  market  value  of 
the  element  of  risk  had  been  thus  worked  out  were  chiefly  con- 
tracts of  maritime  loan,  and  all  were  concerned  with  the  risks 
incurred    in  transport — generally  by  sea.7     It    is  not  surprising, 

1  Bensa,  op.  cit.  3  n.  2,  tells  us  that  in  the  notarial  acts  at  Genoa  we  find  the  ex- 
pressions, nomine  accometidationis,  nomine  venditionis  et  puri  cambii,  muttio  gratis  et 
amore,  used  quite  indifferently. 

2  Ashburner,  op.  cit.  ccxxv  ;  Bensa,  op.  cit.  9. 

3  Ibid  9,  tells  us  that  there  are,  "  innombrables  exemples  de  contrats  de  change 
accompagn£s  de  Tune  des  deux  clauses,  '  rendu  sauf  a  terre,'  ou  '  aux  risques  de 
mer.'  Dans  la  Pratica  della  Mercatura  de  Pegolotti  p.  200,  on  voit  que,  selon 
qu'une  lettre  de  change  tir£e  de  Florence  sur  l'Angleterre  renfermait  l'une  ou  l'autre 
de  ces  clauses,  le  banquier  percevait  une  commission  de  10  sous,  ou  bien  seulement 
de  20  petit  sous  par  100  marcs.  La  difference  de  ses  deux  taux  montre  que,  dans  le 
premier  cas,  on  payait  une  veritable  prime  d'assurance." 

4  Bensa,  op.  cit.  10.  5  Ibid. 

6  Ibid  20  et  seq.  Some  have  wished  to  maintain  that  Portugal  was  the  place 
from  which  the  contract  came ;  Bensa  has  proved  the  correctness  of  the  opinion  of 
Stypmann  and  Pardessus  that  it  comes  from  Italy. 

7  We  do  find,  however,  that  the  risks  of  transport  by  land  were  insured  ;  Bensa, 
op.  cit.  22,  says  that  it  appears  from  the  Florentine  documents  that  contracts  of  insur- 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     277 

therefore,  to  find  that  when  the  contract  of  insurance  first  appears 
as  an  independent  contract,  it  is  modelled  on  the  maritime  loan, 
which  developed  into  the  contract  of  bottomry.1  No  very  large 
modification  was  needed.  In  the  maritime  loan  the  debtor,  who 
has  borrowed  the  money,  declares  that  he  has  received  the  sum 
advanced,  and  promises  to  restore  an  equivalent  sum  on  the  safe 
arrival  of  the  ship  or  goods  :  in  the  insurance  the  insurer  plays  the 
part  of  the  debtor,  states  that  he  has  received  the  amount  for 
which  the  ship  or  goods  are  insured,  and  promises  to  repay  it  in 
the  event  of  the  ship  or  goods  not  arriving  safely.2  It  was  only- 
natural  that  the  earliest  insurers  should  be  shipowners — they  could 
charge  a  smaller  premium  because  they  could  more  easily  guarantee 
a  safe  arrival ; 3  and  it  was  inevitable  that  those  who  drew  up  the 
earliest  contracts  of  insurance  should  be  the  same  persons  as  those 
who  were  in  the  habit  of  drawing  up  contracts  of  loan  on  bot- 
tomry.4 Hence  it  was  from  the  latter  contract  that  some  of  the 
most  important  of  the  technical  terms  applicable  to  insurance  at 
the  present  day  (such,  for  instance,  as  "policy"  and  "premium") 
were  originally  taken.5 

But  later  in  the  century  the  form  changed.  It  came  to  be 
modelled  on  a  sale ; 6  and  the  analogy  of  a  sale  was  used  to  ex- 
plain its  incidents.  The  contract  of  sale  was  adapted  to  the  pur- 
poses of  an  insurance  by  regarding  the  property  insured  as  sold  to 
the  insurer,  subject  to  a  resolutive  condition  in  the  event  of  its 
safe  arrival.  It  was  for  this  reason  that  the  goods  were  at  the 
insurer's  risk  during  the  whole  of  the  voyage,  and  that  he  could 
sue    for    their    recovery   during  this    period."      Two    important 

ance  were  made  "  non  seulement  en  vue  des  risques  des  marchandises  sur  mer,  mais 
aussi  en  vue  des  risques  du  transport  par  terre  "  ;  further  it  seems,  op.  cit  46,  that  the 
premium  for  these  risks  was  about  half  that  for  maritime  risks  ;  but  even  in  the  middle 
of  the  seventeenth  century  this  form  of  insurance  was  comparatively  rare  ;  Marquardus, 
De  Jure  Mercatorum  et  Commerciorum  II.  13.  11  says,  "  ilia  est  super  rebus  quae 
terra,  haec  qua;  mari  transvehuntur ;  rara  ilia  frequens  haec." 

1  Ibid  28  ;  for  this  contract  see  above  261-263. 

2  "  II  y  avait,  toutefois,  une  difference :  tandis  que  dans  la  pret  a  la  grosse  le 
debiteur,  c'est  a  r!ire  l'emprunteur,  declarait  avoir  recu  la  somme  qui  lui  etait  vrai- 
ment  avancee  et  s'engageait  a  restituer  une  somme  equivalente  en  cas  d'arrivee  a  bon 
port ;  dans  l'assurance,  au  contraire,  le  debiteur,  c'est  a  dire  l'assureur,  feignait  d'avoir 
recu  la  somme  assuree,  s'engageant  a  la  payer  a  l'assur£  dans  le  delai  convenu,  sauf 
dans  le  cas  d'arrivee  a  bon  port  du  navire  ou  des  marchandises,"  Bensa,  op.  cit.  28. 

3  Ibid  24.  4  Lefort,  op.  cit.  xi. 

5  Ibid  xi,  xii ;  cp.  ibid  xii  n.  2  citing  Straccha,  De  Assecuratione  Gl.  xv  2  who 
says,  "  trajectitia  pecunia  instar  cujus  assecuratio  inventa  est." 

6  Bensa,  op.  cit.  28 — at  Genoa,  "  a  partir  de  1368,  dans  tons  les  actes  genois  d'assur- 
ance,  l'assure  s'oblige  a  payer  la  somme  assuree  nomine  venditionis  et  puri  cambii." 

7  Two  passages  from  the  Consilia  of  the  Genoese  lawyer  Bosco,  cited  Bensa,  op. 
cit.  29,  30,  make  this  quite  clear — "  Si  contingeretres  vel  merces,  super  quibus  facta 
est  assecuratio,  petdi,  assecurator  solvit  pretium  et  valorem  pro  quo  assecuravit,  et 
recuperat  merces  quae  sunt  suo  periculo  a  se  emptae,  si  recuperari  possunt "  ;  and 
"  Si  contingat  res  illas  super  quibus  est  facta  securitas  capi,  dictas  res  tanquam  etTectaa 
assecuratorum  pro  parte  qua  assecuraverunt  super  ipsis,  per  eos  vindicantur  et  recuper- 


278  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

principles  of  insurance  law  flowed  from  this  conception.  In  the 
first  place,  the  insured  must  be  the  owner,  or  at  least  have  some  in- 
terest in  the  property  insured.1  A  man  cannot  transfer  to  another 
what  he  does  not  own.  Therefore  from  the  first  the  contract  was 
a  true  contract  of  indemnity,  and  not  a  mere  wager  on  the  safe 
arrival  of  ship  or  merchandise.2  In  the  second  place,  if  the  ship 
or  goods  did  not  arrive  safely,  and  the  resolutive  condition  failed 
to  operate,  the  insurers  were  entitled  to  so  much  of  the  property 
insured  as  could  be  recovered.3 

During  the  fourteenth  century  the  business  of  insurance  grew 
and  flourished.  In  the  first  half  of  the  fourteenth  century  Floren- 
tine and  Genoese  merchants  treated  the  cost  of  insurance  as  a 
regular  part  of  the  cost  of  transport.4  Genoa  seems  to  have  been 
the  centre  of  the  insurance  business.  Societies  of  insurance 
brokers,  employed  solely  in  this  business,  were  known  there 5 ;  and 
that  their  business  flourished  can  be  seen  from  the  fact  that,  on  a 
single  day  in  1 393,  a  Genoese  notary  made  more  than  eighty  in- 
surance contracts.6  The  growing  popularity  of  the  contract  natur- 
ally caused  it  to  become  still  further  separated  from  the  contract 
of  loan  on  bottomry,  or  the  contract  of  sale.  Shipowners,  as  such, 
ceased  to  act  as  insurers ;  and  the  magnitude  of  the  sums  assured 
led  to  the  practice  of  several  persons  joining  in  the  contract,  by 
writing  their  names  under  the  policy,  with  the  proportion  of  the 
sum  assured  for  which  they  were  prepared  to  answer.7  Moreover, 
the  form  of  the  contract  tended  to  grow  less  elaborate.  Its  legality 
being  now  fully  recognized,  it  ceased  to  be  disguised  under  the 
form  of  a  loan  or  a  sale.  It  came  to  be  regarded  as  a  distinct 
species  of  the  large  genus  innominate  contract,  reducible  to  the 
formula  "do  ut facias — I  the  insured  give  a  premium  that  you  the 
insurer  may  undertaKe  a  risk."8 

antur,  et  de  ipsis  tanquam  propriis  disponunt,  quasi  tanquam  res  venditae  ex  die  con- 
tracts assecurationis  toto  viagio  fuerint  ipsorum  emptorum  et  assecuratorum  periculo." 
1  Bensa,  op.  c  t.  34.  -  Ibid  34.  3  Above  277  n.  7. 

4  Bensa,  op.  cit.  21 — citing  as  authority  the  books  of  Francesco  del  Bene  and 
Company,  of  Florence. 

5  Ibid  48. 

6  Ibid  47 ;  Bosco  in  no.  369  of  his  Consilia  (there  cited)  says,  "  Marcus  propter 
lucrari  fecit  plures  assecurationes  sicut  faciunt  plurimi  mercatores  de  Janua  quorum 
aliqui  de  nullo  alio  vivunt  quam  de  hujusmodi  quaestu,  qui  quandoque  est  utilissimus, 
quandoque  damnosus,  secundum  discretiones  assecurantium  et  secundum  cursum  tem- 
porum  et  fortunae  blandimenta  vel  adversiones." 

7  Bensa,  op.  cit.  24. 

8  Straccha,  De  Assecuratione,  Introd.  47 — "  Et  illud  quasritur,  rem  tuam  rnari  vel 
terra  exportandam  salvam  fore  promisi  periculum  suscipiens,  et  periculi  gratia  pretium, 
an  nominatus  seu  magis  innominatus  contractus  censeatur  ?  Et  innominatum  con- 
tractum  esse  censit  Baldwinius  .  .  .  suscipio  enim  periculum  ut  des  .  .  .  et  sic  facio 
ut  des  "  ;  equally  also,  if  looked  at  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  insurer,  it  is  a  con- 
tract of  "  Facio  ut  des,"  for  these  innominate  contracts,  "  judicantur  diversi  modo,  ex 
parte  dantis  est  do  ut  facias,  ex  parte  vero  facientis  est  facio  ut  des,  non  inspecto  ordine 
contrahendi,  sicut  in  emptione  et  venditione,  locatione,  et  similibus." 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     279 

In  early  days  there  was  no  rule  as  to  the  form  in  which  the 
contract  must  be  drawn  up.  There  is  reason  indeed  to  think  that, 
in  the  earlier  part  of  the  fourteenth  century,  contracts  of  insurance 
were  sometimes  made  verbally.1  But  the  procedural  advantages 
obtained  by  getting  the  contract  drawn  up  in  writing  by  a  notary 
or  a  sworn  broker,  led  the  parties  in  almost  all  cases  to  adopt  this 
method  of  contracting.2  In  the  first  instance  these  contracts  were 
sometimes  very  informally  drawn.  Mere  notes  of  the  necessary 
clauses  to  be  inserted  in  the  agreement  were  taken.3  Probably 
the  instrument  was  embodied  in  complete  form  only  if  it  was 
necessary  to  take  legal  proceedings  upon  it.4  But  it  is  clear  that 
the  practice  of  employing  sworn  brokers  will  lead  to  the  evolution 
of  a  stereotyped  form.  The  form  which  the  brokers  of  Genoa, 
Florence,  and  Pisa  evolved  in  this  century  has  in  substance 
shaped  the  policies  of  our  modern  law.5  It  was  substantially  the 
form  on  which  Straccha 6  commented  in  the  sixteenth  century  ; 
and  it  was  the  form  which  many  governments  in  the  same  cen- 
tury, partly  for  fiscal  reasons,  and  partly  on  account  of  the 
convenience  of  having  one  definite  form  which  all  traders  under- 
stood, made  obligatory  for  all  insurance  contracts.7 

This  growth  of  the  practice  of  insurance  caused,  in  the  first 
place,  the  ascertainment  and  elaboration  of  the  rules  of  law 
governing  the  contract ;  and,  in  the  second  place,  its  regulation  by 
statutes  which  were  passed,  either  in  the  interests  of  the  state,  or 
in  the  interests  of  the  parties  to  the  contract  Since  these  rules 
and  statutes  are  the  basis  of  the  insurance  law  observed  in  Europe 
and  in  England  at  the  present  day,  we  must  glance  briefly  at 
them. 

(i)  We  have  seen  that,  from  the  first,  the  contract  of  insur- 
ance was  a  contract  of  indemnity,  and  that  therefore  the  person 
insured  must  have  some  interest  in  the  subject  matter  of  the 
insurance.  This  requirement  sometimes  gave  insurers  the  oppor- 
tunity of  evading  their  obligations,  and  led  to  the  insertion  of 
clauses  which   bound   the   insurers   to   pay   whether   or    not    the 

1  Bensa,  op.  cit.  34 — "  Les  documents  que  nous  possedons  admettent,  en  effet,  la 
possibility  de  conclure  le  contrat  cum  scriptura  vel  sine." 

2  Ibid  30.  3  See  the  specimen  cited  ibid  31,  32.  4  Ibid  31. 

5  "  Les  polices  florentines  et  pisanes  etaient  assez  conformes,  dans  leur  ensemble, 
aux  polices  modernes.  .  .  .  Aussi  convient  il  peut-etre  de  conjecturer  qu'a  Genes 
egalement  les  polices  d'assurance  contenaient  ces  clauses  detaillees  dont  les  polices 
florentines  et  pisanes  nous  revelent  l'usage,  et  qu'elles  differaient  par  la  des  instru- 
ments dresses  par  les  notaires,"  ibid  33. 

6  De  Assecuratfone ;  the  form  is  at  the  end  of  the  Introd.,  and  the  rest  of  the 
treatise  consists  of  40  Glosses  on  the  form.  The  form  is  dated  1567 ;  cp.  Bensa, 
op.  cit.  33. 

7  See  Magens,  Insurances  ii  4-7,  for  two  forms  of  policy  prescribed  at  Florence  by 
the  ordinance  of  1523. 


280  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

insured  had  any  interest.1  But  the  prevalence  of  these  clauses 
soon  gave  rise  to  the  serious  evil  of  facilitating,  by  means  of 
insurance,  mere  wagering  contracts  on  the  safety  of  ships  or  other 
property  insured.2  The  merchandise  assured  was,  in  the  earlier 
contracts,  described  with  some  minuteness,  which  gave  place,  in 
later  contracts,  to  a  more  general  description.3  The  ship  on 
which  the  merchandise  was  loaded ,  was  described  ;  and  the  names 
of  the  captain,  the  consignor,  and  owner  were  inserted.4  It  was 
very  rarely  that  the  ship  was  not  designated,  and  the  insured 
allowed  to  load  in  any  ship  he  pleased.5  At  first  the  insurance 
was  always  for  the  voyage.  Time  policies  (which  never  exceeded 
a  year)  were,  however,  introduced  in  the  course  of  the  fourteenth 
century.0  From  the  earliest  time  the  route  was  prescribed  ;  and 
any  deviation,  unless  allowed  by  the  policy,  avoided  the  contract.7 
The  risks  against  which  the  insurance  was  made  were  generally 
carefully  specified  ;  but  generally  they  excluded  risks  arising  from 
the  barratry  of  the  master ;  and  sometimes  certain  other  risks 
also.8  Sometimes  the  policy  specified  a  time  within  which,  in 
default  of  news,  the  ship  was  to  be  presumed  to  be  lost.9  In  case 
of  capture  and  rescue  it  was  a  disputed  point  as  to  whether  the 
insurers  were  liable  to  pay.10  The  better  opinion  seems  to  have 
been  that  they  were  liable ;  and  policies  sometimes  provided  that 
they  should  not  be  liable,  if  they  redeemed  the  goods  and  de- 
livered them  safely  at  their  destination.11  The  one  duty  of  the 
insured  was  to  pay  the  premium ;  and  this  payment  must  always 
be  made  in  advance.12     Sometimes  provision  was  made  for  the 

1  Bensa,  op.  cit.  35,  citing  Bosco,  Consilia  392  p.  611 — «'  nisi  instrumenta 
assecurationum  essent  ita  lati  et  ita  ampli  tenoris,  fatui  essent  facientes  se  assecurari 
quia  assecuratores  propter  non  solvere  mille  cavillationes  excogitarent." 

2  Ibid  36. 

3  Ibid  37 — eventually,  "  ou  on  vient  meme  a  ne  plus  specifier  que  les  objets 
precieux  et  certaines  categories  de  marchandises ;  pour  toutes  les  autres,  on  em- 
ployait  la  formule  generate  super  rebus,  et  mercibus." 

4  Ibid  38.  5  Ibid  38,  39.  6  Ibid  39. 

7  Ibid  39-41 — the  question  what  amounted  to  a  deviation  seems  to  have  given  rise 
to  a  good  many  questions. 

8  Ibid  42-44 ;  see  especially  the  clause  taken  from  a  Florentine  policy  of  1397 
cited  at  p.  43 — "  Les  risques  que  les  assureurs  courent  .  .  .  sont  ceux  de  Dieu,  de  la 
mer,  des  gens,  du  feu,  du  jet  a  la  mer,  de  la  retention  par  le  fait  des  Seigneurs  ou  des 
Communes  ou  de  toute  autre  personne,  ou  de  repr^sailles,  ou  d'arret,  et  de  tout  autre 
cas,  peril,  fortune,  empechement  ou  sinistre  qui,  de  quelque  facon  que  ce  soit,  pourrait 
se  produire,  ou  se  serait  produit,  et  quels  que  puissent  etre  les  cas  et  dans  quelques 
conditions  qu'ils  se  r^alisent,  excepts  ce  qui  pourrait  concemer  le  lest  et  la  douane." 

9  Ibid  44. 

10  Ibid  44  ;  for  similar  doubts  in  English  law  see  below  291. 

11  Ibid  44. 

12  Ibid  45 — as  M.  Bensa  says,  this  custom  as  to  payment  in  advance  may  have 
originated  when  the  contract  took  the  form  of  a  fictitious  sale ;  under  this  form  the 
insurer  declared  that  he  had  received  the  sum  for  which  the  property  was  insured ; 
and,  when  the  contract  took  this  form,  "  l'assureur  n'aurait  pas  eu  d'action  pour  en 
poursuivre  le  payement  "  ;  later  this  custom  passed  jnto  enacted  law, 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     281 

cancellation  of  the  policy  and  the  return  of  the  premium,  if  e.g., 
owing  to  the  abandonment  of  the  voyage,  the  risk  was  never 
incurred.1 

(2)  The  earliest  legislation2  on  the  subject  of  insurances 
comes  from  Genoa  and  Florence.  The  earliest  enactment  is  a 
Genoese  statute,  which  comes  from  the  last  quarter  of  the  four- 
teenth century.3  It  was  directed  to  the  prohibition  of  insurances 
on  foreign  ships — a  prohibition  which  was  never  very  effectual, 
and  was  shortly  afterwards  repealed,4  and  to  laying  down  certain 
other  conditions  as  to  the  validity  of  the  contract.  For  instance, 
insurances  made  after  the  loss  was  known  were  declared  to  be 
void ;  and  the  loss  was  deemed  to  be  known  if  any  one  person 
had  heard  the  news.5  Other  statutes  were  passed  to  impose  a  tax 
upon  insurances,5  to  settle  the  form  of  the  contract,7  and  to 
provide  a  short  and  effective  procedure  for  the  enforcement  of 
claims  upon  insurance  policies.3  Towards  the  end  of  the  fifteenth 
century,  the  greater  freedom  allowed  to  the  parties  to  make  what 
terms  they  pleased,  led  to  an  increase  in  the  practice  of  making 
insurance  contracts  solely  for  the  purpose  of  wagering  ;  and  the 
legislature  at  Genoa  made  attempts  to  prohibit  them,  which  were 
not  very  successful.9  But  none  of  these  statutes  covered  very 
much  ground.  It  is  to  the  statutes  of  Barcelona  that  we  must 
look  for  the  first  comprehensive  code  of  insurance  law.10  These 
statutes,  as  finally  codified  in  1484,  have  had  a  large  influence 
upon  the  insurance  law  of  the  rest  of  Europe,  partly  because,  being 
printed  and  circulated  with  the  Consolato  del  Mare,  they  shared 
its  fame  and  influence ; u  and  partly  because,  being  compiled  at  a 
later  period  than  the  earliest  Italian  legislation,  the  law  was  more 
settled,  and  therefore  better  fitted  for  codification.12  They  were 
a  model  for  the  various  codes  of  insurance  law  which  the  chief 

1  Bensa,  op.  cit.  46-47. 

3  On  this  legislation  generally  see  ibid  chaps,  v-vii. 

3  Ibid  52 — we  have  not  got  its  text,  but  we  can  gather  its  substance  from  the 
commentary  contained  in  the  Consilia  of  Bosco  ;  it  must  be  before  1383.  as  an  addition 
to  it  was  made  in  that  year,  ibid. 

4  Ibid  54 — repealed  in  1408  for  fiscal  reasons ;  for  similar  laws  elsewhere  and 
their  modification  see  ibid  53,  81-85. 

3  Ibid  52,  53 — the  loss  is  known  if  it  has  come  to  the  knowledge  of  a  single 
person. 

*  Genoa  (1401)  ibid  53. 

7  Florence  (1523)  Magens,  Insurances  ii  1  §  2. 

8  Bensa,  op.  cit.  72-S0;  see  e.g.  the  Venetian  law  of  1468,  cited  ibid  80. 

9  Ibid  84-88,  104  ;  M.  Bensa  seems  to  dispose  successfully  of  the  view  of  Prof. 
Vivante  that  the  growth  and  extension  of  insurance  contracts  was  due  to  the  use  made 
of  them  to  make  wagers  ;  as  M.  Bensa  says,  "  assurement,  les  paris  ont  contribue  a 
augmenter  le  nombre  de  ces  contrats  ;  mais  ce  n'est  qu'apres  qu'ils  etaient  deja 
devenus  frequents,  grace  a  la  realite  du  besoin  auquel  ils  donnaient  satisfaction." 

10  For  the  text  of  the  statutes  see  Pardessus,  Lois  Maritimes  v  493-554,  507-5 13  ; 
they  are  summarized  by  Bensa,  op.  cit.  chap.  vi. 

'*  Ibid  50  ;  for  this  code  see  vol.  v  70-71.  12  Bensa,  op.  cit,  50,  51,  57,  5S. 


282  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

trading  countries  of  Europe  passed  in  the  sixteenth  and  seven- 
teenth centuries.1 

This  legislation  is  comprised  in  five  statutes  which  were 
passed  at  Barcelona  from  143 5- 1484.  They  deal  with  all  aspects 
of  insurance  law,  and  settle  the  leading  principles  which  underlie 
it.  The  statute  of  1435  2  is  the  basis  of  the  later  law.  Among 
other  topics,  it  deals  with  the  capacity  of  the  parties,3  insurances 
on  foreign  ships,4  the  proportion  which  the  value  of  the  property 
insured  must  bear  to  the  amount  of  the  insurance 5  the  rules  as  to 
presumption  of  loss,'5  the  regulation  of  insurance  brokers,7  the 
payment  of  the  premium,8  the  form  of  the  contract,9  the  procedure 
to  enforce  it 10  Some  small  modifications  were  made  in  the  follow- 
ing year  ; u  and  in  1 4  5  8 12  considerable  modifications  were  made  in 
the  direction  of  allowing  greater  freedom  to  insurers  and  insured.13 
Additional  rules  were  made  as  to  the  payment  of  the  premium,14 
as  to  proof  of  the  loss,15  and  as  to  the  procedure  to  enforce  the 
contract ; 1(i  and  there  were  some  new  rules  as  to  the  cancellation 
of  the  policy  when  the  risk  was  not  incurred.17  In  1461  18  evasions 
of  the  rules  as  to  insurances  on  foreign  ships,  by  making  use  of 
the  machinery  of  a  sale  or  a  loan,  were  prohibited.  In  148419  all 
these  rules  were  summed  up  in  the  comprehensive  code  which,  as 
I  have  said,  has  had  a  very  large  influence  on  the  development  of 
the  law  throughout  Europe.20  The  chief  change  made  was  the 
abolition  of  all  restrictions  on  the  insurance  of  foreign  ships.21 
But  this  freedom  obviously  tended  to  encourage  mere  wagering 
policies.  In  order  to  discourage  them,  insurances  on  ships  or 
cargoes  sailing  beyond  the  Straits  of  Gibraltar,  were  prohibited, 
unless  they  were  destined  for  Barcelona;22  and  rules  were  made 
to  suppress  the  practice  of  insuring  non-existent  cargoes.23  Further 
provisions  were  made  to  invalidate  contracts  made  after  the  loss 

1  For  the  text  of  some  of  these  later  laws  see  Magens,  op.  cit.  ii  23-30 — Antwerp 
1563  ;  ibid  30-49 — Spanish  ordinances  of  1556,  1588,  and  1618. 

2  Pardessus,  op.  cit.  493-502.  3  §  3.  4  §  1.  5  §§  2,  4. 

6  §15-  7§§8,  17-20.  8§n.  »§g.  10§§  12-14. 

11  Pardessus,  op.  cit.  502-504.  la  Ibid  507-521.  13  §  1. 

14  §  12.  «  §  14.  16  §§  8,  9,  18-22.  17  §§  14.  15. 

18  Pardessus,  op.  cit.  521-523.  19  Ibid   523-543. 

20  "  Les  veritables  Ordinations  sobre  les  seguretats,  qui,  traduites  en  plusieurs 
langues,  ont  exerce  une  si  grande  influence  sur  la  jurisprudence  maritime  de  la 
Mediterrande,  et  aux  quelles  Ton  a  coutume  de  se  reTerer  quand  on  parle  de  la  ported 
de  lois  de  Barcelone,  ne  sont  pas  autre  chose  que  l'ordonnance  de  1484,  ou  la  matiere 
re^ut  sa  r£glementation  definitive,"  Bensa,  op.  cit.  67. 

21  §I-  •        ,x     ■ 

22  §  2  ;  as  Bensa  says,  op.  cit.  68 — "  les  assurances  in  quovis  n  etaient  pas 
admises  par  le  droit  maritime  Catalan.  La  crainte  des  simulations  et  des  paris,  qui 
avait  inspire"  cette  restriction,  6tait  telle  qu'elle  eut  pour  r£sultat  de  faire  deTendre 
absolument  les  assurances  portant,  soit  sur  les  marchandises  .  .  .  voyageant  au  dela 
du  d^troit  de  Gibraltar  .  .  .  soit  sur  les  batiments  naviguant  dans  les  memes 
parages." 

a3§9- 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     283 

had  occurred,1  and  as  to  the  presumption  of  loss  from  the  non- 
receipt  of  news. 

These  statutes  give  us,  as  M.  Bensa  has  pointed  out,  a  very 
complete  picture  of  the  insurance  law  of  the  fifteenth  century. 
They  are,  as  I  have  said,  especially  important  in  the  early  history 
of  this  contract  in  England  and  in  other  European  countries  ;  for 
it  was  the  Italian  and  Spanish  insurance  law  of  this  century  which 
was  already  making  its  influence  felt  in  the  trading  cities  of  the 
Netherlands  and  was  soon  to  make  its  appearance  in  England.2 
To  its  adventures  in  England  we  must  now  turn. 


The   Introduction   and  Development   of  the    Contract  of  Marine 
Insurance  in  England 

As  we  might  expect,  the  earliest  mention  of  a  policy  of  insur- 
ance in  England  is  to  be  found  among  the  records  of  the  court  of 
Admiralty.  Insurance,  as  was  pointed  out  in  a  sixteenth-century 
petition  to  the  Council,  "  is  not  grounded  upon  the  lawes  of  the 
realme,  but  [is]  rather  a  civill  and  maritime  cause,  to  be  determined 
and  discided  by  civilians,  or  els  in  the  highe  courte  of  the 
Admiraltye."  3  This  earliest  policy  is  to  be  found  in  the  record 
of  the  case  of  Broke  c.  Maynard*  (1547),  in  which  an  action  was 
brought  by  the  insured  on  a  policy  written  in  Italian,  and 
subscribed  by  two  underwriters.  The  action  was  defended  on  the 
ground  that  the  insurers  had  already  paid  part  of  the  sum,  and 
that  they  had  received  no  part  of  goods  which  had  been  salved. 
It  was  further  alleged  that  there  had  been  a  deviation.  The  case 
shows  that  at  this  date  the  practice  of  insurance  was  well  known 
in  England  ;  and  that  this  was  the  fact  was  specifically  stated  in 
the  case  of  Ridolphye  c.  Nunez 5  (1562),  in  which  the  custom  in 
the  city  of  London  of  making  insurances  through  agents  is  thus 
set  out  in  the  pleadings  :  "The  use  and  custome  of  makynge  bylls 
of  assuraunce  in  the  place  commonly  called  Lumbard  Strete  of 
London,  and  likewyse  in  the  Burse  of  Antwerpe,  is  and  tyme  out 

2  Genoese  underwriters  were  established  at  Bruges  in  1370,  Bensa,  op.  cit.,  101 ; 
"L'Espagne  d'abord  et  pour  peu  de  temps  d'ailleurs,  puis  la  Flandre,  l'Angleterre  et 
la  France,  en  recueillant  les  traditions  et  les  coutumes  de  l'ltalie,  lui  succ^derent 
dans  la  mission  de  les  developer  conformement  aux  transformations  amenees  par  la 
marche  du  temps,  et  aux  formes  nouvelles  du  commerce  terrestre  et  maritime," 
ibid  105. 

3  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  Ixxvi. 

4  Ibid  47;  possibly  the  case  of  Emerson  c.  De  Sallanova  (1545),  ibid  lxvi,  which 
turned  upon  a  claim  on  an  indemnity  given  against  the  withdrawal  of  a  safe  conduct 
by  the  king  of  France,  may  be  an  earlier  case  of  insurance ;  cp.  Vance,  Essays 
A.A.L.H.  iii  no. 

'Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  52,  53;  in  1573-1574  insurance  is  referred 
to  as  an  ancient  custom  among  merchants,  Dasent,  viii  195-196. 


284  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

of  mynde  hath  byn  emongst  merchants  usinge  and  frequentinge 
the  sayde  several  1  places,  and  assuraunces  used  and  observed,  that 
the  partie,  in  whose  name  the  bill  of  assuraunce  is  made,  ys  not 
bounde  to  specifie  in  the  same  whether  the  goods  assured  are  for 
his  owne  or  for  any  other  man's  accompte.  .  .  .  And  yf  any 
mys fortune  chauncethe  to  the  same  gooddes  in  such  sort  assuryd, 
the  sayde  partie,  in  whose  name  the  byll  of  assuraunce  is  made, 
maye  demande  and  oughte  to  recover  them  againste  the  assurers 
by  vertue  of  the  sayd  custome  as  his  owne  propre  gooddes, 
although  they  perteyne  to  some  other.  ...  And  further  he 
doothe  alledge  that  commonly  merchants,  by  all  the  tyme  above 
declared,  have  and  doo  cause  ther  gooddes  to  be  assured  from 
porte  to  porte  by  ther  factors  and  other  ther  frends  havinge  noo 
interest  or  propretie  in  the  gooddes  assured,  and  yet  thassuraunce 
goodd,  and  thassurers  bounde  tanswere  the  losse  of  such  gooddes 
yf  any  happen." 

The  Italian  origin  of  insurance  law  is  clear  on  the  face  of  the 
policies  which  we  find  in  the  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty.1 
The  earliest  policy  which  appears  there  is,  as  we  have  seen,  written 
in  Italian ; 2  and  in  form  they  are  very  similar  to  the  Italian 
policies  of  this  period.  A  comparison  between  some  of  them,  and 
the  form  of  policy  prescribed  by  the  Florentine  legislation  of  I  $23* 
will  make  this  quite  clear.  They  are  not  of  course  precisely 
similar.  They  are  not  drawn  up  in  one  stereotyped  form,  and 
they  therefore  vary  both  in  length  and  in  contents.  Some  are 
quite  short,  while  others  contain  larger  and  more  elaborate  clauses. 
Two  policies  contain  a  "sue  and  labour"  clause;4  and  a  Dutch 
policy  of  1638  contains  a  renunciation  of  the  Antwerp  Insurance 
Orders,  and  an  agreement  to  submit  to  arbitration  in  the  case  of 
any  disagreement.5  But  the  clause  which  nearly  all  the  English 
policies  of  this  period  contain — which  in  a  modified  form  our 
modern  policies  of  marine  insurance  still  retain — to  the  effect  that 
this  policy  shall  be  of  as  much  force  and  effect  as  the  surest  writ- 
ing or  policy  heretofore  made  in  Lombard  Street,6  probably  had 
the  result  of  producing  a  uniformity  in  the  legal  effect  of  all  these 

1  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  45-59. 

2  Ibid  47.  3  Magens,  op.  cit.  ii  4-7. 

4  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  56,  58,  59 ;  below  290. 

5  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  59. 

6 In  the  policy  of  1547,  ibid  48,  the  clause  runs  as  follows:  "As  for  the  aventure 
that  the  assurers  shall  stande  at,  it  is  to  be  understoode  that  this  preasente  writinge 
hathe  as  muche  forse  as  the  beste  made  or  dieted  byll  of  surance  which  is  used  to  be 
made  in  this  Lombarde  Streete  of  London  "  ;  in  the  form  of  marine  insurance  set  out 
in  the  first  schedule  to  the  Marine  Insurance  Act  1906,  6  Edward  VII.  c.  41,  it  runs 
as  follows  :  "  And  it  is  agreed  by  us,  the  insurers,  that  this  writing  or  policy  of  assur- 
ance shall  be  of  as  much  force  and  effect  as  the  surest  writing  or  policy  of  assurance 
heretofore  made  in  Lombard  Street,  or  in  the  Royal  Exchange,  or  elsewhere  in 
London," 


CONTRACT  OF  xMARINE  INSURANCE     285 

policies.  It  showed  that  the  parties  intended  to  incorporate  into 
their  contracts  the  rules  of  the  law  merchant  generally  understood 
to  be  applicable  to  them  ; 1  and  it  therefore  enabled  the  parties  to 
appeal  to,  and  the  court  to  apply,  these  rules  in  any  litigation 
which  might  arise. 

The  growth  of  England's  foreign  trade  in  the  latter  part  of 
the  sixteenth  century  increased  the  importance  of  insurance  law ; 
and,  from  1574  onwards,  the  Council  began  to  consider  the 
expediency  of  putting  this  new  business  under  some  form  of 
regulation,  and  of  providing  some  means  by  which  the  rights  of 
the  parties  under  insurance  contracts  could  be  quickly  and  easily 
enforced.  That  the  Council  might  be  informed  as  to  the  actual 
rules  observed,  an  order  was  sent  in  1574  to  the  Lord  Mayor  ot 
London  to  collect  and  certify  the  orders  made  and  the  rules 
applied  by  the  merchants  in  matters  of  insurance.2  But  nothing 
was  done  that  year,  although  the  order  was  repeated.3  In  1575 
the  Lord  Mayor  was  further  directed  to  fix  the  prices  for  making 
and  registering  policies  of  insurance.4  But  apparently  nothing 
was  done,  as  later  in  the  same  year  he  was  again  directed  to 
summon  experienced  merchants  and  civilians,  and,  with  their  help, 
to  collect  this  information  and  reduce  it  to  writing ; 5  and  it  was 
necessary  to  repeat  the  order  in  1576.6 

In  the  meantime  the  Council  had  resolved  to  act  upon  its  own 
knowledge,  and  to  adopt  two  measures,  which  may  well  have  been 
suggested  by  the  practice  of  other  commercial  nations.  In  the 
first  place,  they  proposed  to  regulate  the  business  of  insurance  by 
setting  up  an  office  for  the  making  and  registering  of  insurances. 
In  the  second  place,  they  proposed  to  create  a  special  commission, 
consisting  of  merchants  and  civilians,  for  the  speedy  trial  of  these 
cases,  in  order  that  the  merchants  might,  "  the  better  followe  theire 
trades  without  incomberaunce  or  molestinge  the  one  the  other  by 
suites  at  lawe,  bothe  to  the  hinderance  of  traffick  and  of  her 
Majesty's  customes."7 

1  Thus  the  Council  tell  the  Lord  Mayor,  whom  they  had  directed  to  write  down 
the  rules  and  orders  relating  to  insurance,  to  follow  the  customs  of  other  countries 
as  to  the  fees  payable. 

2  Dasent  viii  321.  '  Ibid  337. 

4  Ibid  397.  s  Ibid  ix  43  (1575). 

6  Ibid  163 — "  Whereas  letters  have  been  often  written  to  him  and  his  predeces- 
sours  to  consider  for  some  order  to  be  made  for  matters  of  assuraunce,  the  wante 
whereof  doth  dailie  brede  grete  trebles,  he  is  now  required  to  sende  unto  their 
Lordships  without  delaie  that  hath  been  doune  in  that  behalf,  and  also  the  perfect  note 
of  the  rates  that  hath  ben  set  downe  for  the  registering  of  assuraunces,  and  therein  to 
use  the  more  expedicion  for  that,  upon  the  certaine  knowledge  thereof,  their  Lordships 
are  to  precede  therein  to  the  furtheraunce  of  her  Majesties  service." 

7  That  this  was  their  object  was  stated  in  a  letter  written  by  the  Council  to  the 
chief  justice  of  the  King's  Bench  and  the  judge  of  the  Admiralty  in  1601,  Dasent  xxxi 
253  ;  as  it  was  said  in  a  petition  to  the  Council  in  1570,  "  the  matter  .  .  .  constethe 
and  standeth  muche  uppon  the  orders  and  usages  of  merchauntes  by  whom  rather  than 


28(5  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

(i)  The  regulation  of  the  business  of  insurance  took  the  form, 
usually  followed  in  the  sixteenth  century  both  in  England  and 
abroad,  of  the  grant  to  an  individual  of  a  monopoly  right  to  make 
and  register  insurances,  and  to  charge  fees  for  his  services.1  It 
was  a  plan  which  provided  regulation,  and,  not  only  paid  its  own 
way,  but  also  might  be  made  to  provide  some  revenue  to  the 
government.  About  the  year  i  574  a  grant  was  made  to  Richard 
Candler,  giving  to  him  and  his  deputies  the  sole  right  of  making 
and  registering  "  insurances  and  policies  and  other  instruments 
belonging  to  merchants.""  It  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  both 
the  notaries 3  and  the  brokers 4  protested ;  and  very  probably  it 
was  the  delay  caused  by  these  objectors,  which  caused  the  Lord 
Mayor  to  be  so  slow  in  returning  to  the  Council  the  information 
about  insurances,  which  it  desired  him  to  collect.5  Notwithstand- 
ing this  remonstrance,  the  grant  took  effect,  and  it  is  probable  that 
it  was  the  origin  of  the  "Office  of  Assurances"  mentioned  in  the 
statute  of  i6oi.c  But,  in  order  to  meet  the  objectors,  the  Council, 
as  we  have  seen,7  directed  the  Lord  Mayor  of  London  to  nominate 
commissioners  to  consider  the  question  of  fees  and  regulations. 
These  commissioners  proceeded  to  settle  the  fees  which  could  be 
taken  in  the  Office,  and  to  make  regulations  which  permitted 
others,  besides  Candler  and  his  deputies,  to  draw  up  policies.8  To 
this  Candler  not  unnaturally  made  objections,  which  are  contained 
in  a  paper  which  he  sent  to  Walsingham  in  1576.9     It  is  probable 

by  course  of  law  yt  may  be  forwarded  and  determyned,"  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty 
(S.S.)  ii  lxxvi. 

1  Vol.  iv  346-347 ;  see  the  regulations  for  the  registration  of  insurances  contained 
in  the  Guidon  de  la  Mer,  cited  Martin,  History  of  Lloyd's  42-44 ;  and  it  would  seem 
that  there  was  a  similar  office  at  Antwerp,  ibid  39. 

2  We  have  an  account  of  this  monopoly  in  the  protests  against  it  made  by  the 
notaries  and  brokers,  which  John  Strype  printed  in  his  edition  of  Stow's  Survey 
(published  1720)  ii  142;  Martin,  History  of  Lloyd's  36-41,  has  also  given  the  material 
portions ;  the  whole  of  it  is  printed  by  Tawney  and  Power,  Tudor  Economic  Docu- 
ments ii  246-251. 

3 The  notaries  (sixteen  in  number)  stated  that  they  "lived  upon  the  making  of 
policies,  intimations,  renunciations  and  other  writings  granted  unto  the  said  Candler," 
and  that  this  grant  would  mean  their  utter  overthrow;  cp.  Scott,  Joint  Stock 
Companies  iii  364;  for  the  notaries  see  vol.  v  78-79,  114-115. 

4  The  brokers  (thirty  in  number)  complained  that  the  grant  was  a  gross  infringe- 
ment of  the  liberty  of  the  subject,  and  prophesied  that  it  would  open  the  door  to  many 
inconveniences  to  the  merchants — "  If  all  this  serving  merchants  occasions  should  be 
committed  to  one  particular  person,  it  were  not  possible  but  great  discommodities 
and  losses  would  happen  to  many  for  lack  of  dispatch  .  .  .  that  it  would  be  a  great 
bondage  to  merchants  to  be  tied  to  one  particular  person,  who  might  either  for  favour 
or  reward  dispatch  one  man,  and  for  displeasure  or  ill-will  delay  another." 

5  Above  285. 

6  43  Elizabeth  c.  12  ;  Malynes,  Lex  Mercatoria  105, 106. 

7  Above  285.  8  Martin,  History  of  Lloyd's,  39-41. 

9  "  Yf  evvery  man  maye  make  pollicies  that  will,  the  case  will  be  souche  that  the 
saide  Richard  Candeler  shal  not  have  the  regestringe  of  the  tenthe  pollecy  of 
assewraunce  that  shal  be  made,  for  that  he  shall  not  knowe  on  whom  to  complayne 
for  not  registring  their  assewraunces.  And  so  his  said  office  shall  not  be  able  to 
cowntervaille  his  charges,"  ibid  40. 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     287 

that  the  rates  found  by  the  commissioners  were  accepted  as  fair 
by  the  government.  On  the  other  hand,  the  government  insisted 
upon  all  insurances  being  registered  at  the  Office,  and  perhaps 
upon  the  sole  right  of  making  them,  conferred  upon  Candler  or 
his  deputies.1  As  it  was  said  in  a  marginal  note  on  Candler's 
petition,  it  was  on  these  provisions  in  the  patent  that  the  govern- 
ment relied  for  the  redress  of  "  deceipt  in  Assewraunces  "  ;  -  and, 
though  the  notaries  and  brokers  remained  unsatisfied,  there  is  no 
evidence  that  the  merchants  seriously  objected.3  After  all,  similar 
regulations  were  in  force  in  continental  countries. 

(2)  For  the  trial  of  insurance  cases  the  Council  appointed  a 
body  of  commissioners.  We  have  not  got  the  list  of  commissioners  ; 
but  it  would  appear  that  they  consisted  of  merchants  and  civilians,4 
and  that  the  judge  of  the  court  of  Admiralty  was  the  chief  com- 
missioner.5 Whether  or  no  they  included  any  common  lawyers  I 
cannot  say.  But,  in  at  least  one  important  case,  merchants,  civil- 
ians, and  common  lawyers  were  included  in  the  commission.'' 
The  object  which  the  Council  had  in  view  was,  as  they  explained 
at  a  later  date,  to  provide  that  "  soche  dyfferences  as  might  fall 
out  betwixt  merchantes  touchinge  this  matter  should  be  handled 
and  decyded  amonge  themselves  by  soche  as  have  best  knowledge 
and  experience  in  those  affaires." "  It  is  thus  clear  that,  here 
again,  the  Council  intended  to  follow  foreign  precedents,  and 
establish  a  mercantile  court  consisting  of  both  merchants  and 
lawyers,  which  should  administer  mercantile  custom  without  those 
formalities  of  procedure  and  pleading  which  delayed  the  hearing 
of  cases  in  the  regular  courts  of  law.8 

But,  though  tribunals  of  this  kind  were  found  to  be  perfectly 

1  Dasent  ix  177  (1576) ;  Martin,  op.  tit  40. 

*"So  longe  as  every  man  maye  make  his  owen  pollecy  the  decipt  in 
Assewraunces  will  nevir  be  redressed,  which  is  the  greatest  cause  of  the  erection  of 
the  saide  Office,"  ibid  40,  41.  It  was  probably  owing  to  the  trouble  over  Candler's 
Patent  that  in  1576  one  Henriques  Roderiguez  petitioned  for  a  monopoly  of  the 
brokerage  of  insurances,  promising  to  pay  hah"  the  penalties  imposed  on  those  who 
infringed  this  monopoly  to  the  Queen,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  xvi. 

3  It  would  appear  from  the  letter  of  the  Council  in  1601,  Dasent  xxxi  252-253,  that 
the  merchants  complained,  not  of  the  existence  of  the  regulations,  but  of  their 
ineffectiveness. 

*  Ibid  x  232  (1578);  xi  360,  393  (1579-1580);  xii  25,  69,  199  (1580);  see  ibid 
199,  200  for  a  case  sent  to  them  by  the  Council  and  recommended  by  the  French 
ambassador — apparently  the  insurers  had  refused  to  pay. 

*  Ibid  xiii  359-360  (1581-1582) ;  on  one  occasion,  xiv  214  (1586),  four  civilians  were 
appointed  arbitrators,  and  on  another  occasion  two  civilians  and  the  judge  of  the 
Admiralty,  xx  202  (1590-1591). 

*  Ibid  ix  168,  230  (i576)—the  persons  named  were  the  Master  of  the  Rolls,  Jus- 
tice Southcote,  Sir  Thomas  Gressham,  Dr.  Hamond,  Dr.  Forde,  Edward  Osbume, 
Alderman  Barne,  Thomas  Alderzey,  Benedict  Spinola,  and  Hectour  Nonnez ;  and 
later  the  two  Chief  Justices  were  added ;  it  was  stated  that  the  case  was,  "  so  strainge 
as  requireth  the  advice  and  consultation  of  such  as  be  experienced  in  those  kinde  of 
dealinges." 

7  Ibid  xxxi  253.  s  See  vol.  v  150. 


288  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

satisfactory  on  the  Continent,  this  tribunal  set'  up  by  the  Council 
was  not  a  success.  In  1601  the  merchants  "that  use  to  assure 
goodes,"  stated,  in  a  petition  to  the  Council,  that  the  orders  made 
by  the  merchants  and  confirmed  by  the  Council  were  not  obeyed  ; 
and  that  some  refused  "to  submytte  and  conforme  them  selves  to 
the  order  of  Commyssioners  appointed  to  heare  those  causes, 
beinge  chosen  of  skillfull  merchantes  and  sworne  by  the  order  of 
the  Lord  Maior  to  deale  indyfferently  and  uprightlie,  to  the  great 
trouble  of  honest  traders  and  the  incouradgement  of  soch  mer- 
chantes as  have  no  meanynge  to  performe  their  bergaines. " : 

The  reason  for  the  failure  of  the  insurance  commissioners  is 
probably  to  be  found  in  the  fact  that  both  the  court  of  Admiralty 
and  the  courts  of  common  law  continued  to  exercise  a  competing 
jurisdiction ;  and  that  both  were  eager  to  retain  and  to  enlarge  it 
In  1547  the  Admiralty  proceeded  against  a  plaintiff  for  contempt 
because  he  had  sued  in  the  city  of  London  court;2  and  in  1556 
it  proceeded  against  another  plaintiff  because  he  had  sued  before 
a  commission  appointed  by  the  Chancellor.3  In  the  common  law 
courts  there  is,  it  is  true,  only  one  reported  case  during  this  cen- 
tury of  an  action  upon  a  policy  of  insurance.4  But  the  action  of 
assumpsit,  as  developed  in  the  latter  part  of  this  century,  was  quite 
capable  of  affording  a  remedy  upon  these  policies  ;  and  Malynes 5 
tells  us  that  many  such  actions  were  brought.  It  is  clear  that 
these  competing  jurisdictions  afforded  many  opportunities  to  the 
dishonest  and  the  litigious.  Such  persons  could  put  pressure  on 
their  opponents  by  a  refusal  to  submit  to  the  summary  jurisdiction 
of  the  commissioners,  which  would  compel  them  to  have  recourse 
to  a  formal  trial  before  a  law  court.0  And,  even  if  the  case  were 
brought  before  the  commissioners,  it  would  seem  that  they  some- 
times declined  to  obey  their  orders,  perhaps  under  the  plea  that 
legal  proceedings  were  pending  in  the  Admiralty  or  at  common 
law.  The  fact  that  the  Council  had  not  given,  and  indeed  could 
not  give,  exclusive  jurisdiction  to  these  commissioners  was  fatal  to 
their  efficiency. 

1  Dasent  xxxi  252,  253. 

2  Broke  c.  Maynard,  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  47. 

3  Ibid  lxvii. 

4  A  case  of  1589  cited  in  Dowdale's  case  (1606)  6  Co.  Rep.  at  p.  47  b. 

5  Op.  cit.  106 — he  explains  that  he  attended  before  the  committees  engaged  on 
the  Act  of  1601,  and  that  it  passed  with  some  difficulty,  "because  there  were  many 
suits  in  law  by  action  of  Assumpsit  before  that  time,  upon  matters  determined  by  the 
Commissioners  for  Assurances,  who  for  want  of  power  and  authority  could  not  compel 
contentious  persons  to  perform  their  ordinances." 

°"  Of  late  years  divers  persons  have  withdrawen  themselves  from  that  arbitrarie 
course  (i.e.  settlement  by  arbitration),  and  have  soughte  to  drawe  the  parties  assured 
to  seeke  their  moneys  of  everie  severall  Assurer,  by  Suites  commenced  in  her 
Majesties  Courtes,  to  their  greate  charges  and  delayes,"  43  Elizabeth  c.  12 
Preamble. 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     289 

In  consequence  of  the  petition  of  the  merchants  to  the  Council 
in  1 60 1,1  the  chief  justice  of  the  King's  Bench  and  the  judge  of 
the  Admiralty  were  directed  to  hold  an  enquiry ; 2  and  the  result 
of  this  enquiry  was  a  resolution  to  strengthen  the  jurisdiction 
of  the  commissioners,  by  giving  it  statutory  authority.  The 
statute  of  1 60 1,  which  was  passed  with  some  difficulty  through 
Parliament,3  evidently  intended  to  set  up  for  London  a  com- 
mercial court  of  the  ordinary  continental  type,  for  the  hearing  of 
actions  upon  policies  of  marine  insurance.  The  preamble  sets  out 
the  antiquity,  the  prevalence,  and  the  advantages  of  the  custom  of 
marine  insurance,  and  recites  the  measures  taken  to  decide  the 
controversies  arising  by  the  arbitration  of  commissioners.  The 
statute  then  enacts  that  the  Lord  Chancellor  shall  be  empowered 
to  appoint  a  standing  commission  to  hear  all  cases  arising  upon 
all  policies  of  insurance  entered  in  the  London  Office  of  Insurances. 
This  commission  was  to  consist  of  the  judge  of  the  Admiralty,  the 
recorder  of  London,  two  doctors  of  the  civil  law,  two  common 
lawyers,  and  eight  "grave  and  discrete  merchants."  These  com- 
missioners, or  any  five  of  them,  were  to  adjudicate  upon  insurance 
cases  "  in  a  briefe  and  summarie  course,  as  to  theire  discretion 
shall  seeme  meete  withoute  formalities  of  pleadinges  or  proceed- 
ings."4 They  were  given  power  to  examine  on  oath,  or  to 
commit  to  prison  those  who  disobeyed  their  final  decrees.5  An 
appeal  from  their  decision  could  be  brought  to  the  court  of 
Chancery ;  but  execution  was  not  to  be  suspended  pending  an 
appeal.6  The  commissioners  were  to  be  sworn  to  act  honestly, 
and  no  commissioner  interested  in  any  case  could  take  any  part 
in  the  decision  of  that  case.7 

Thus  a  commercial  tribunal  of  the  continental  type8  was  for 
the  first  time  established  in  England  by  statutory  authority.  But 
it  suffered  from  two  grave  defects.  Firstly,  its  jurisdiction  was 
confined  to  policies  registered  in  the  London  Office  of  Insurances, 
so  that  it  did  not  extend  to  insurances  made  in  other  seaport 
towns.  Secondly,  it  did  not  exclude  specifically  the  jurisdiction 
of  the  courts  of  common  law  and  the  court  of  Admiralty.  It  is 
possible  that,  if  the  king  and  Council  had  continued  to  exercise 
the  control  over  the  courts  which  they  exercised  in  the  Tudor 
period,  these  defects  might  have  been  remedied.  But  the  consti- 
tutional controversies  of  the  seventeenth  century  were  fatal  to 
institutions  which  depended  upon  the  prerogative.     The  Office  of 

1  Above  288.  3  Dasent  xxxi  252,  253. 

3  Malynes,  op.  cit.  106.  *  §  1.  5  §  2. 

8  §  3 — the  sentence  must  be  satisfied  or  the  money  deposited  with  the  Commis- 
sioners. 

7 §4.  "Vol.  v  150. 

VOL.  VIII.— 19 


290  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

Insurances  seems  to  have  disappeared ;  and  the  new  court  was 
left  to  wage  an  unequal  contest  with  the  victorious  common  law. 
There  was  indeed  an  attempt  in  1662  to  remedy  certain  minor 
defects  in  the  Act.1  For  instance,  the  necessary  quorum  was 
reduced  from  five  to  three ; 2  and  power  was  given  to  punish 
parties  or  witnesses  who  refused  to  appear,3  to  make  orders 
against  the  person  or  goods  of  a  defendant,4  and  to  issue  com- 
missioners to  examine  witnesses  beyond  the  sea.5  But  these 
amendments  were  wholly  ineffectual  in  the  face  of  the  determined 
opposition  of  the  common  lawyers.  They  held  that  a  judgment 
of  the  court  was  no  bar  to  subsequent  proceedings  at  law  ; 6  that 
it  could  hear  disputes  only  as  to  policies  of  marine  insurance ; 7 
and  that,  even  in  these  cases,  it  could  act  only  when  it  was  the 
insured  who  was  plaintiff.8 

The  natural  result  was  that,  during  the  sixteenth  and  seven- 
teenth centuries,  the  law  of  insurance  was  in  a  very  backward 
state.  Neither  in  the  court  of  Admiralty  in  the  earlier  part  of 
this  period,  nor  in  the  courts  of  common  law  and  equity  in  the 
latter  part,  were  any  very  general  or  certain  rules  evolved.  This 
fact  is  proved  by  some  of  the  decisions  of  these  tribunals. 

In  the  court  of  Admiralty  it  is  assumed  in  several  cases  that 
the  contract  of  insurance  is  a  contract  of  indemnity.  It  follows 
that  the  insurer  who  has  paid  is  entitled  to  the  goods  salved,  on 
paying  salvage  for  them ; 9  and  that,  if  goods  salved  were  not 
made  over  to  the  insurers,  they  were  not  liable  to  pay  the  sum 
assured.10  It  was  in  order  to  induce  the  insured  to  do  their  utmost 
to  salve  the  goods  for  the  benefit  of  the  insurers  that  the  "  sue  and 
labour"  clause  was  inserted  in  these  policies.11     It  is  fairly  clear 

1 13,  14  Charles  II.  c.  23.  2§  2.  1. 

3§2.  2.  4§§3- 2,  5.  1.  5§3-  1. 

"Came  v.  Moye  (1658)  2  Sid.  121. 

7  Denoyr  v.  Oyle  (1649)  Style  166-167— There  was  however  a  doubt  whether  the 
court  might  not  have  jurisdiction  on  a  life  policy  if  the  assured  was  going  to  sea  "  on 
merchants  affairs." 

8  Delbye  v.  Proudfoot  (1693)  1  Show.  3g6. 

9  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  149  (1573),  Lopez,  an  insurer,  gets  recap- 
tured goods,  paying  salvage. 

10Cavalchant  c.  Maynard  (1548)  ibid  ii  45 — in  a  defence  to  an  action  on  a  policy 
it  is  stated  that,  "yf  any  of  the  goods  so  assured  shulde  within  the  tyme  of  assurance 
.  .  .  fall  to  any  wrack  .  .  .  and  yet  sume  parte  of  the  same  happen  to  be  savyd 
that  parte  .  .  .  which  shulde  be  so  saved  .  .  .  oughte  to  be  devyded  equallye  be- 
twene  thassurers  .  .  .  accordinge  to  every  assurers  proporcion  .  .  .  before  any 
assurance  can  be  demanded  of  them  "  ;  Broke  c.  Maynard  (1547)  ibid  ii  47 ;  cp.  ibid  ii 
lxx  (1573)  action  for  freight  on  wine  brought  to  London  by  insurers  after  the  ship  had 
been  wrecked. 

11  Ibid  ii  56 — a  French  policy  of  1565  ;  58— a  Dutch  policy  of  1638  ;  in  the  former 
policy  the  clause  runs,  "  And  we  gyve  to  him  .  .  .  ample  powar  to  helpe  and  gyve 
order  for  to  save  them  said  shippes  and  marchandises  or  part  of  the  same  to  sell  and 
distribute  them  yf  ned  be  aswell  to  our  prouffytte  as  dommage  withowte  asking  us 
leave  or  license.  And  we  shall  paye  all  charges  averedge  and  expenses  whiche  shall 
beren  at  the  sewte  and  saving  of  them  said  shippes  and  merchaundisses  be  yt  that 
there  be  anything  recovered  or  not." 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     291 

that  deviation  was  a  defence  to  an  action  on  a  policy ; l  and  that 
no  news  of  a  ship  for  a  year  was  presumptive  evidence  of  its  loss.2 
We  can  see  the  influence  of  the  continental  rules  in  the  assumption 
that  a  reassurance  is  invalid ; 3  but  apparently  an  insurance  upon 
the  goods  of  alien  enemies  was  at  this  period  valid4 — though, 
after  some  conflict  of  opinion,  such  insurances  have  been  finally 
decided  to  be  invalid.5  It  is  clear  too  that  the  benefit  of  a  policy 
could  be  assigned.6 

In  the  courts  of  common  law  it  was  clear  that  deviation  was 
fatal  to  the  policy ; 7  but  that  for  a  loss  occurring  before  the  devia- 
tion the  insured  could  recover.8  There  were  also  a  few  cases  as 
to  the  interpretation  of  the  risks  borne  by  the  insurers.  It  was 
held  at  law  that  pirates  were  a  "  peril  of  the  sea  "  ; 9  and  in  equity 
that  the  term  "  restraint  of  princes  "  did  not  cover  a  restraint  due 
to  the  wilful  default  of  the  insured.10  The  ship  and  goods  insured 
were  at  the  peril  of  the  insurers  till  the  ship  arrived  and  was  un- 
loaded, if  the  policy  was  so  expressed  ; n  but  in  England,  as 
abroad,  there  was  some  doubt  as  to  the  insurer's  liability  if  the  ship 
was  captured,  and  then  recaptured,  before  being  taken  infra 
prasidia}%  It  was  clear  that  when  the  ship  had  been  taken  infra 
prasidia  and  condemned,  the  original  owner  lost  his  property  in 
her;13  and  Holt  ruled  in  1699  that,  as  the  property  in  the  ship 
was  gone,  the  insurer  was  freed  from  liability.14  But,  as  late  as 
1 7 1 2,  the  question  was  treated  as  open  to  argument,  though  the 
court  inclined  to  adopt  Holt's  view.15  There  was  an  important 
case,  noticed  by  several   reporters,  upon  the  stipulation  that  the 

1  Broke  c.  Maynard  (1547)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  47. 

2  De  Salizar  c.  Blackman  (1555)  ibid  ii  49 ;  cp.  ibid  lxviii  (1562-1563) — a  year  and 
a  day  is  the  period  stated ;  it  was  to  obviate  questions  of  this  kind  that  the  clause 
"  lost  or  not  lost "  was  inserted  in  insurances,  Malynes,  op.  cit.  107. 

3  Ravens  c.  Hopton  (1561)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  120. 

4Ibidii,  xv,  lxviii  (1562-1563) ;  lxx  (1569-1570) ;  cp.  Park,  Marine  Insurance  (1st  ed.) 
15,  16 ;  and  see  above  281-283  for  the  earlier  continental  rules. 

'Furtado  v.  Rogers  (1802)  3  B.  and  P.  191,  overruling  Lord  Mansfield's  view  in 
Planche  v.  Fletcher  (1779)  1  Dougl.  251. 

6  Duckett  c.  Barne  (1570)  Select  Pleas  of  the  Admiralty  (S.S.)  ii  143. 

7  Green  v.  Young  (1702)  2  Salk.  444 ;  this  decision  is  really  the  converse  to  earlier 
cases  which  held  that  loss  after  a  deviation  enabled  the  holder  of  a  bottomry  bill  to 
sue,  Western  v.  Wildy  (1684)  Skin.  152;  cp.  Williams  v.  Steadman  (1694)  Holt, 
K.B  126. 

8  Green  v.  Young  (1702)  2  Salk.  444. 

9  Pickering  v.  Barkley  (1672)  2  Rolle  Ab.  248 — the  merchants  gave  evidence 
that  this  was  the  view  held  by  the  court  for  assurance  cases ;  s.c.  reported  by 
Style  132 ;  cp.  Barton  v.  Wolliford  (1688)  Comb.  56. 

10  (1690)  2  Vern.  176.  u  Anon.  (1685)  Skin.  243. 

12  Above  280.  13Anon.  (1642)  March  N.R.  no. 

14  Anon.  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  724. 

15Assievedo  v.  Cambridge  (1712)  10  Mod.  77 — a  report  of  the  arguments  of  the 
civilians ;  on  this  argument  the  court  inclined  in  favour  of  the  insurer,  but  the  point 
was  ordered  to  be  argued  by  the  common  lawyers  in  the  following  term ;  cp.  Park, 
op.  cit.  81-82. 


292  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

ship  was  "warranted  to  depart  with  convoy."  It  seems  to  have 
been  settled  that  the  stipulation  was  satisfied  if  she  so  departed, 
even  though  she  was  afterwards  separated  by  tempest,  and 
captured.1  The  question  of  the  possibility  of  parol  variations  of  a 
policy  gave  rise  to  two  decisions.2  It  was  settled  both  at  law  and 
in  equity  that  if  the  risk  was  not  run  the  premium  could  be 
demanded  back.3  The  court  of  Chancery i  differing  from  the  courts 
of  law,5  held  that  if  the  insured  had  no  interest  the  policy  was 
void.  Whether  the  fact  of  having  advanced  money  on  bottomry 
was  a  sufficient  interest  was  not  perfectly  clear. 

It  is  obvious  that  these  few  cases  cover  very  little  ground.  It 
is  also  obvious  that  it  was  owing  to  the  defects  of  the  procedure  of 
the  common  law  courts  and  the  court  of  Chancery  that  the  cases 
were  so  few.  At  common  law  it  was  necessary  to  bring  a  separate 
action  against  each  of  the  underwriters ;  and  either  the  under- 
writers or  the  insured  could  compel  their  opponent  to  proceed  to 
trial  on  all  these  actions."  If  a  case  was  reserved,  counsel  were 
left  to  draw  it  up  at  their  leisure.7  These  cases  were  often 
argued  in  private,  so  that  the  decision  could  never  be  a  guide  to 
any  future  case.8  In  fact  not  much  guidance  could  be  expected 
from  such  of  these  cases  as  were  heard  in  open  court,  since  both 
judges  and  counsel  were  ignorant  even  of  the  meaning  of  the 
ordinary  technical  terms  used  by  merchants  and  seamen ; 9  and 
the  judge  consequently  left  the  case  to  the  jury  without  any  ex- 
planation of  the  principles  applicable.10  It  was  apparently  the 
custom  always  to  hear  two  arguments ; u  and  in  these,  as  in  other 

1  Jefferies  v.  Legendra  (1692)  Carth.  217;  s.c.  3  Lev.  321 ;  2  Salk.  443  ;  1  Show. 
320 — a  long  report  of  the  argument  for  the  plaintiff;  4  Mod.  58;  cp.  Lethulier's  Case 
(1693)  2  Salk.  443 ;  Bond  v.  Gonsales  (1704)  2  Salk.  445. 

2  Kaines  v.  Sir  R.  Knightly  (1682)  Skin.  54 ;    Bates  v.  Grabham  (1703)  2  Salk. 


445 
263 
716 


3  Martin  v.  Sitwell  (1692)  1  Show.  156 ;   Deguilder  v.  Depeister  (1684)  1  Vern. 
4Goddard  v.  Garrett  (1692)  2  Vern.  269;    Harman  v.  Vanhatton  (1716)  2  Vern. 


sAssievedo  v.  Cambridge  (1712)  10  Mod.  77  at  p.  80;  Depaba  v.  Ludlow  (1721) 
1  Comyns  360. 

6  Park,  op.  cit.  xli ;  cp.  Goram  v.  Fouke  (1672)  2  Keble  722  ;  and  the  preamble, 
to  43  Elizabeth  c.  12,  cited  above,  288  n.  6. 

7  Park,  op.  cit.  xliii.  8  Ibid  xlii. 

9  See  Pepys,  Diary  iii  363-365,  for  an  amusing  account  of  the  trial  of  an  insurance 
case  in  1663  before  Hyde,  C.J.,  at  the  Guildhall — "it  was  pleasant  to  see  what  mad 
sort  of  testimonys  the  seamen  did  give,  and  could  not  be  got  to  speak  in  order;  and  then 
their  terms  such  as  the  judge  could  not  understand  ;  and  to  hear  how  sillily  the  counsel 
and  judge  would  speak  as  to  the  terms  necessary  in  the  matter,  would  make  one 
laugh." 

10  "  In  former  times  the  whole  of  the  case  was  left  generally  to  the  jury,  without 
any  minute  statement  from  the  bench  of  the  principles  of  law,  on  which  insurances 
were  established;  and  as  the  verdicts  were  general,  it  is  almost  impossible  to  deter- 
mine from  the  reports  we  now  see,  upon  what  grounds  the  case  was  decided,"  Park 
op.  cit.  xlii. 

"  Ibid  xliii. 


CONTRACT  OF  MARINE  INSURANCE     293 

cases,  it  was  always  possible  to  delay  the  proceedings  at  law  by 
filing  a  bill  in  equity.1  Nor  was  the  court  of  equity  any  more 
satisfactory.  Its  delays  were  notorious.'2  It  was  out  of  touch 
with  commercial  life  and  ways  of  thought.  The  somewhat  over- 
fine  standards  of  morality,  which  it  was  beginning  to  require,  were 
hardly  suited  to  the  world  of  trade.  A  court,  for  instance,  which 
could  decide  that  it  would  not  assist  the  holder  of  a  bottomry  bond 
because  it  carried  unreasonable  interest,3  which  refused  to  accept 
the  value  set  upon  the  goods  in  a  valued  policy,4  was  obviously 
out  of  touch  with  the  elementary  principles  of  commercial  and 
maritime  law  applicable  to  these  transactions. 

If  we  compare  the  state  of  the  law  of  insurance  at  the  end  of 
the  seventeenth  century  with  its  state  at  the  end  of  the  sixteenth 
century,  we  can  see  that  it  has  made  no  appreciable  progress.  At 
neither  period  had  there  been  any  legislation,  comparable  to  that 
of  continental  states,  directed  against  obvious  abuses,  such  as  the 
practice  of  cloaking  mere  wagers  under  policies  of  insurance.  At 
neither  period  had  much  progress  been  made  in  the  work  of  con- 
verting those  mercantile  customs  and  that  continental  jurisprudence, 
which  Malynes  describes,5  into  ascertained  rules  of  English  law. 
In  one  respect  indeed  there  had  been  retrogression.  The 
business  of  underwriting  was  subject  to  some  sort  of  control  in  the 
sixteenth  century ;  but  in  the  seventeenth  century,  that  control 
ceased  with  the  disappearance  of  the  Office  of  Assurances.6  It 
was  not  till  the  early  part  of  the  following  century  that  the  Legis- 
lature attempted  to  repress  some  of  the  abuses  which  were  dis- 
figuring the  law ;  and  it  was  not  till  later  in  that  century  that 
Lord  Mansfield  evolved  from  mercantile  custom  and  foreign 
precedents  the  principles  of  our  modern  law.  Similarly  we  must 
look  to  the  same  period  for  the  humble  beginnings,  at  Lloyd's 
coffee  house,  of  the  voluntary  association  which  has  supplied,  far 
more  efficiently  than  any  governmental  institution,  that  measure 
of  control  over  the  business  of  underwriting  which  had  been 
attempted  by  the  Council  in  the  sixteenth  century. 


1Vol.  i  465  and  n.  4;  Thus  in  Harman  v.  Vanhatton  (1716)  2  Vern.  716,  a  plain- 
tiff, having  recovered  on  an  insurance,  brought  an  action  on  a  bottomry  bond,  alleging 
that,  though  the  ship  was  lost,  there  had  been  a  deviation ;  a  bill  was  then  filed  in 
equity  to  stay  this  action,  which  was  dismissed. 

2  Vol.  i  423-424,  426,  437-439. 

3  Dandy  v.  Turner  (1701)  1  Eq.  Cas.  Abr.  372 ;  cp.  the  remarks  on  this  case  made 
by  Park,  op.  cit.  477,  478. 

4Le  Pypre  v.  Farr  (1716)  2  Vern.  716. 

5  Op.  cit.  chaps,  xxv,  xxvii,  xxviii. 

6 In  1693-1694  Luttrell,  Diary  iii  264,  mentions  a  project  "to  make  his 
majestie  sole  insurer  of  all  ships  at  a  moderate  rate,  which  should  lye  in  bank  at  the 
custome  house,  to  answer  the  merchants  losses  "  ;  but  it  came  to  nothing. 


294  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

The  Origins  of  Other  Forms  of  Insurance 

I  have  dealt  so  far  only  with  marine  insurance.  During  the 
whole  of  this  period  it  was  by  far  the  most  important  branch  of 
insurance  law.  It  was  the  only  branch  which  the  Council  at- 
tempted to  regulate ;  and  it  was  the  only  branch  which  the 
Legislature  noticed. 

Analogous  to  insurances  against  the  risks  of  transport  by  sea 
are  insurances  against  the  risks  of  transport  by  land.  We  have 
seen  that  this  species  of  insurance  was  known  abroad  ; *  and  per- 
haps it  was  known  in  England2 — though  there  is  not  much 
evidence  as  to  this.3  Gradually,  in  addition  to  these  insurances 
of  property  against  the  risks  of  transport,  insurances  against  other 
dangers  to  property  developed.  But,  during  the  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth  centuries,  the  only  other  danger  to  property  which 
could  be  insured  against  was  danger  by  fire ;  and  as  yet  it  was 
only  houses  that  could  be  insured.4  As  early  as  1 591  a  system  of 
fire  insurance  was  in  operation  in  Hamburg ;  and  proposals  to 
establish  this  kind  of  insurance  in  England  had  been  made  in  1635 
and  1638.5  But  it  was  not  till  after  the  Great  Fire  that  it  was 
actually  established.  In  1 66j  Barbon  established  an  office  which, 
in  1680,  was  transferred  to  a  company."  In  1682  the  City  of 
London  started  a  rival  undertaking.7  About  the  same  time  two 
partners  established  a  mutual  society,  known  as  the  Friendly 
Society ;  and  in  1696  another  mutual  society,  known  as  the  Hand 
in  Hand,  was  started.8 

But,  before  fire  insurance  had  developed,  insurances  against 
risks,  not  to  property,  but  to  the  person,  were  known  both  on  the 

1  Above  276  n.  7. 

2  Malynes,  op.  cit.  107 — "other  assurances  are  made  upon  goods  and  merchan- 
dises sent  by  land  from  one  place  to  another,  by  the  conductors  or  carriers  to  Venice, 
Frankford,  or  any  other  places,  wherein  the  goods  commonly  are  declared,  and  the 
mark  also :  and  this  manner  of  assurance  is  especially  performed  by  the  conductors, 
who  take  for  the  charges  a  certain  allowance  for  every  pound  weight  that  the  goods 
do  weigh,  and  moreover,  2,  3  or  4  upon  the  hundred  pounds  in  value  that  the  said 
goods  are  esteemed  to  be  worth :  and  he  doth  appoint  a  sufficient  guard  of  souldiers 
to  convey  the  same  by  land  and  rivers  to  the  places  intended,  which  nevertheless  by 
a  stronger  power  have  many  times  been  taken  by  the  freebooters." 

3  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  374  n.  2,  cites  the  Merchant's  Dayly  Companion 
(1684)  355,  in  which  mention  is  made  of  insurances  of  goods  "sent  by  wagon  or  cart 
etc.  by  land  from  all  robbers  or  thieves." 

4  It  was  not  till  1706  that  Charles  Povey  founded  an  office  to  insure  against  losses 
of  goods  and  merchandise  by  fire,  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  374. 

6  Ibid  iii  372.  6  Ibid.  7  Ibid  373  ;  Luttrells  Diary  i  135. 

8  Scott,  Joint  Stock  Companies  iii  373;  it  is  there  pointed  out  that  there  was  a 
difference  between  the  Joint  Stock  and  the  Mutual  Societies — "  the  former,  through 
the  security  deposited  in  the  names  of  trustees,  were  in  a  position  to  pay  claims,  even 
although  the  sums,  received  from  premiums,  had  already  been  exhausted.  A  mutual 
society  on  the  other  hand  was  constituted  on  the  basis  of  exacting  less  for  premiums, 
and  making  up  any  deficit,  when  required,  by  a  levy  upon  its  members." 


OTHER  FORMS  OF  INSURANCE       295 

continent  and  in  England  Of  the  early  history  of  this  form  of 
insurance  I  must  say  a  few  words. 

In  modern  times  the  contract  of  insurance  against  risks  to  the 
person  takes  the  form  either  of  life  or  accident  insurance ;  and 
both  are  very  different  in  character  from  the  insurances  against 
risks  to  property.  Life  insurance  is  a  contract  of  indemnity  in  so 
far  as  it  enables  the  insured  to  make  provision  against  death  or 
the  incapacities  of  old  age.  But  it  is  also  both  in  England  ]  and 
elsewhere  ■  a  method  of  investment ;  and  it  is  this  aspect  of  the 
contract  which  is  the  most  important,  and  causes  it  to  differ 
essentially  from  insurances  against  risks  to  property.  Insurances 
against  risks  to  property  are,  as  we  have  seen,3  simply  contracts 
of  indemnity.  The  result  is  that,  if  the  loss  occurring  from  the 
happening  of  the  risk  is  otherwise  made  good,  the  insurer  is  not 
liable,  because  the  loss  has  not  been  incurred.  On  the  other  hand, 
the  contract  of  life  insurance  is  not  simply  a  contract  of  indemnity. 
It  is  an  absolute  promise  to  pay  at  the  death  of  the  insured  a 
fixed  sum  of  money,  in  consideration  for  the  payment  of  certain 
premiums  during  life,  the  amount  of  which  is  calculated  by  ref- 
erence to  the  probable  duration  of  the  life  insured.4  The  amount 
insured  is  payable  whether  or  not  any  loss  is  incurred  as  a  result 
of  the  death ;  and  in  this  important  respect  the  contract  of 
accident  insurance  resembles  the  contract  of  life  insurance.5 

During  this  period  we  can  see  nothing  resembling  the  modern 
contracts  of  life  or  accident  insurance.  The  statistical  knowledge, 
which  has  rendered  those  contracts  possible  in  modern  times,  was 
wholly  wanting ; 6  and  even  if  it  had  been  available,  it  is  probable 

1  Below  n.  4. 

2  Bensa,  op.  cit.  89—"  L'assurance  sur  la  vie,  telle  qu'on  la  concoit  aujourd'hui, 
n'est,  a  proprement  parler,  un  veritable  contrat  d'indemnite.  Au  fond,  cet  acte  de 
prevoyance  revient  a  n'etre  que  l'accumulation  des  epargnes  qu'il  est  loisible  a  tout 
particulier  de  faire  selon  sa  condition  de  fortune,  le  role  de  la  Compagnie  qui  assure  se 
bornant  a  garantir  a  l'assure  qu'une  mort  prematuree  ne  viendra  pas  empecher  la  for- 
mation du  capital  qu'il  a  entrepris  de  constituer  par  ses  economies." 

3  Above  278,  290. 

4  This  is  clearly  explained  by  Page  Wood,  V.C.,  in  Law  v.  London  Indisputable 
Life  Policy  Co.  (1855)  x  Kay  and  J.  at  p.  228 ;  he  said  :  "  policies  of  insurance  against 
fire  or  marine  risk  are  contracts  to  recoup  the  loss  which  parties  may  sustain  from 
particular  causes.  When  such  loss  is  made  good  aliunde,  the  companies  are  not  liable 
for  a  loss  which  has  not  occurred ;  but  in  a  life  policy  there  is  no  such  provision.  The 
policy  never  refers  to  the  reason  for  effecting  it.  It  is  simply  a  contract  that  in  con- 
sideration of  a  certain  annual  payment,  the  company  will  pay  at  a  future  time  a  fixed 
sum,  calculated  by  them  with  reference  to  the  value  of  the  premiums  which  are  to  be 
paid,  in  order  to  purchase  the  postponed  payments  "  ;  cp.  Dalby  v.  India  and  London 
Life  Assurance  Co.  (1854)  15  C.B.  at  p.  387 ;  "life  assurance,"  said  Parke,  B.,  "is  a 
mere  contract  to  pay  a  certain  sum  of  money  on  the  death  of  a  person,  in  consideration 
of  due  payment  of  a  certain  annuity  for  his  life,  the  amount  of  the  annuity  being 
calculated  in  the  first  instance  according  to  the  probable  duration  of  his  life." 

5Bradburn  v.  The  Great  Western  Railway  (1874)  L.R.  10  Ex.  1. 
•Valery,  Les  Origines  De  L' Assurance  sur  le  Vie  7-10;  Pardessus,  op.  cit.  v. 
331-332,  thought  that  it  was  possible  that  the  contract  of  marine  insurance  was  able  to  be 


296  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

that  the  dangers  and  uncertainties  of  life  in  a  comparatively 
turbulent  age  would  have  made  these  contracts  commercially 
impossible.  But  we  do  see  in  Italy  in  the  Middle  Ages,  and  in 
England  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  a  few 
insurances  against  certain  risks  to  the  person,  which  we  can  regard 
as  the  germs  from  which  our  modern  life  and  accident  insurances 
have  grown  up. 

M.  Bensa  has  shown  that  in  Italy  in  the  Middle  Ages  there 
are  instances  of  contracts  of  insurance  against  certain  kinds  of  risks 
to  the  person.1  There  are  insurances  against  risks  of  pregnancy,2 
against  death  by  the  plague,3  or  against  death  generally  for  a 
certain  limited  period.4  It  is  interesting  to  note  that  in  some  of 
these  policies,  as  in  modern  life  policies,  there  are  stipulations  as 
to  the  parts  of  the  world  to  which  the  insured  may  travel.  But 
it  is  probable  that  these  insurances  were  never  very  frequent — the 
definition  of  the  contract  of  insurance  given  by  Straccha  in  the 
sixteenth  century  does  not  cover  them.5  And,  when  they  began 
to  develop,  they  were  so  often  made  a  disguise  for  mere  wagers, 
that  they  were  prohibited  in  Italy,  Spain,  and  the  Netherlands.6 
Consequently  they  never  developed,  as  marine  insurance  developed, 
into  an   independent   form   of  contract.     The   specimens   which 

developed  in  Italy  because  the  progress  made  in  mathematical  studies  gave  insurers 
some  basis  for  the  calculation  of  risks ;  but,  as  Bensa,  op.  cit.  47-48,  says,  as  yet  no 
proof  of  the  truth  of  this  conjecture  has  appeared.  The  fact  that  it  was  marine  insur- 
ance that  was  principally  developed,  and  the  fact  that  the  risks  were  pretty  constant 
and  well  known,  would  seem  to  point  to  the  fact  that  the  risk  was  calculated  by  the 
practical  instinct  of  the  parties  to  the  contract ;  as  Bagehot  says,  Economic  Studies  g, 
"  men  of  business  have  a  solid  judgment — a  wonderful  guessing  power  of  what  is 
going  to  happen — each  in  his  own  trade." 

1  According  to  Petrus  Santerna,  De  Assecurationibus  et  Sponsionibus  Mercatorum, 
Pars  Secunda  §§  7-21,  the  legality  of  insurances  upon  various  miscellaneous  events 
was  determined  by  considering  whether  a  stipulation,  made  conditional  on  the  happen- 
ing or  not  happening  of  these  events,  would  have  been  valid;  as  "omnis  causa  non 
inhonesta,  etiam  extranea,  justificat  stipulationem  "  (§  18),  so  on  all  events  not  illegal 
or  immoral  an  insurance  can  be  made;  apparently  even  mere  wagering  contracts 
(§§  21-23)  are  valid,  provided  that  the  wager  is  not  made  upon  any  illegal  game  or 
event — though,  "  magis  solatii  causa  quern  lucri  concipiuntur." 

2  Bensa,  op.  cit.  90-94 ;  at  Genoa  a  person  accused  of  illicit  connection  with  an- 
other's slave  was  presumed  to  be  the  father  of  the  child,  if  the  slave,  and  her  master 
and  mistress  (being  persons  of  good  repute)  swore  to  their  belief  in  his  guilt,  and  there 
was  any  other  corroborating  fact ;  such  a  person  was  liable  to  a  heavy  fine,  which 
was  doubled  if  the  slave  died ;  it  was  this  risk  which  was  frequently  the  subject  of 
insurance. 

3  Ibid  97.  4  Ibid  95. 

5  De  Assecuratione,  Introd.  46 — "  Assecuratio  est  alienarum  rerum,  sive  mari,  sive 
terra  exportandarum  periculi  susceptio,  certo  constituto  pretio." 

6  Val£ry,  Les  Origines  de  L' Assurance  sur  la  Vie  5 ;  a  good  illustration  of  this 
legislation  is  to  be  found  in  §  xxxii  of  an  Ordonnance  of  Philip  II.,  which  was  pub- 
lished by  the  Duke  of  Alva  while  he  was  governor  of  the  Netherlands ;  it  runs  as 
follows :  "  et  pour  empecher  les  abus,  fraudes,  dols,  et  crimes  commis  a  l'occasion  des 
assurances  sur  la  vie  des  personnes,  et  des  gageures  sur  voyages  et  autres  inventions 
semblables,  nous  les  avons  prohibees  et  deTendues,  les  prohibons  et  d^fendons  comme 
nuisibles  et  contraires  au  bienetre  general  et  comme  de  mauvais  example,"  Pardessus, 
op.  cit.  iv  116. 


OTHER  FORMS  OF  INSURANCE       297 

M.  Bensa  has  collected  are  in  the  form  of  a  sale.  The  insurer  de- 
clares that  he  has  bought  a  certain  amount  of  property  from  the 
insured,  and  that  he  has  promised  to  pay  a  fixed  price  for  this 
property  by  a  certain  date — the  date  being  that  on  which  the 
risk  terminates.  The  fixed  price  represents  the  amount  of  the 
insurance.  It  is  then  declared  that  if  a  certain  event — the  risk 
insured  against — does  not  happen,  the  money  is  not  to  be  pay- 
able. 

There  is  some  evidence  that  contracts  of  this  kind  were  known 
in  England  during  this  period.1  In  the  only  two  cases  on  the 
subject  which  have  got  into  the  books  we  have  an  insurance  upon 
the  life  of  one  who  was  going  abroad,2  and  an  insurance  upon  the 
life  of  a  certain  person  for  one  year ; 3  and  Rolle  says  that  the 
latter  form  of  insurance  was  in  common  use  both  among  merchants 
and  others.4  In  other  words,  we  get,  as  in  the  Middle  Ages,  in- 
surances in  view  of  certain  definite  risks,  or  for  a  definite  period. 
But,  it  would  seem  from  Rolle's  statement,  that  these  insurances 
were  beginning  to  be  used  more  extensively  than  in  the  Middle 
Ages ;  and  Rolle's  statement  is  corroborated  by  Malynes. 
Malynes  says:5  "Other  Assurances  are  made  upon  the  lives  of 
men,  for  divers  respects,  some  because  their  estate  is  meerly  for 
term  of  life,  and  if  they  have  children  or  friends  to  leave  some 
part  of  their  estate  unto,  they  value  their  life  at  so  many  hundred 
pounds,  for  one  or  more  years,  and  cause  that  value  to  be  assured 
at  five,  six,  ten,  or  more  for  every  hundred  pounds,  and  if  he  do 
depart  this  life  within  that  time,  the  assurors  pay  the  money ;  as 
it  happened  of  late,  that  one  being  ingaged  for  Sir  Richard  Martin 
knight,  Master  of  the  Mint,  caused  ^300  to  be  assured  upon  the 
life  of  the  said  Sir  Richard,  being  some  ninety  years  of  age,  and 
therefore  gave  twenty  and  five  pro  centum  to  the  assurors :  the 
ancient  knight  died  within  the  year,  and  the  said  assurors  did  pay 
the  money.  Also  one  Master  Kiddermaster  having  bought  an 
office  of  the  six  clerks  of  the  Chancery,  and  taken  up  money  of 
others,  caused  for  their  assurance  for  many  years  together  two 
thousand  pounds  to  be  assured  upon  his  life  after  four  and  five  in 

1  There  is  an  account  in  the  records  of  the  court  of  Admiralty  of  an  action  between 
the  representatives  of  William  Gibbons  and  sixteen  underwriters,  who  had  insured  his 
life  from  June  18,  1583,  for  twelve  months;  the  insurance  was  for  the  sum  of 
£383  6s.  8d.  and  the  premium  was  8  per  cent. ;  the  insured  died  May  29,  1584,  and 
the  underwriters  disputed  payment  on  the  ground  that  the  insurance  only  lasted  for 
twelve  periods  of  twenty-eight  days ;  the  court  gave  judgment  for  the  representatives 
of  Gibbons,  Encycl.  Brit.  tit.  Insurance. 

2  Denoyr  v.  Oyle  (1649)  Style  166-167. 

sSir  Robert  Howard's  case  (1700)  2  Salk.  625 ;  s.c.  1  Ld.  Raym.  480. 

*  "  Issint  si  home  garrant  que  tiel  home  viver  a  un  an,  car  ceo  est  le  common  use 
del  securers  enter  marchants  et  autres,  Trin.  39  Eliza.  B.R.,"  Rolle,  Ab.  Action  sur 
case  (A)  3  i  p.  97. 

5  Op.  cit.  107. 


298  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

the  hundred,  until  he  had  paid  that  money;  which  is  very  com- 
modious. Likewise  a  traveller  undertaking  a  voyage  to  Jerusalem 
or  Babylon,  delivering  out  money  payable  at  his  return,  will 
providently  assure  a  sum  of  money  upon  his  life,  either  to  secure 
some  men  that  do  furnish  him  with  money  to  perform  his  voyage, 
and  to  put  forth  the  greater  sum,  or  to  leave  some  means  unto  his 
friends,  if  he  should  die  and  never  return." 

Malynes  makes  it  clear  that  these  kinds  of  insurances  against 
personal  risk  were  beginning  to  be  used  somewhat  as  they  are  used 
in  modern  times.  It  was  beginning  to  be  discovered  that  "  men 
cannot  invent  or  imagine  anything  but  the  value  of  it  may  be 
assured."  l  But  as  yet  this  discovery  was  a  new  thing.  It  is  not 
till  the  eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries  that  the  legal  incidents 
and  consequences  of  these  new  forms  of  insurances,  whether  against 
personal  risks  or  against  risks  to  property  other  than  risks  of 
transport,  begin  to  be  defined. 


The  developments  of  legal  doctrine  described  in  this  chapter 
show  that,  by  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  foundations 
of  English  commercial  and  maritime  law  had  been  laid.  Commer- 
cial law,  and  large  parts  of  maritime  law,  had  ceased  to  be  separate 
bodies  of  law,  and  were  being  absorbed  into  the  system  of  English 
law.  It  was  only  those  parts  of  maritime  law,  which  were  still 
administered  by  the  court  of  Admiralty,  which  as  yet  remained  to 
some  extent  outside  that  system.  The  accomplishment  of  this 
result  had  necessarily  involved  a  large  reception  of  foreign 
principles ;  but  those  principles  had  been  modified  by  contact  with 
a  common  law  which,  as  the  result  of  the  political  controversies  of 
the  seventeenth  century,  had  won  a  position  of  supremacy  in  the 
state ;  and  they  were  being  adapted  to  a  legal  system  in  which  the 
law  was  supplemented  by  a  system  of  equity  administered  in  a 
distinct  tribunal.  As  I  have  already  pointed  out,  the  need  for 
this  modification  and  adaptation  caused  the  development  of 
English  commercial  and  maritime  law  to  be  slower  than  in  states 
where  they  were  administered  in  separate  tribunals,  which  applied 

1  Malynes,  op.  cit.  107 ;  this  is  illustrated  by  a  tale  about  a  lottery  told  by  Pepys' 
Diary  iv  192;  in  this  lottery  each  ticket  cost  £10  and  there  was  only  one  blank,  and, 
says  Pepys,  "  the  wisest  man  I  met  with  was  Mr.  Cholmley,  who  insured  as  many  as 
would,  from  drawing  of  the  one  blank  for  i2d ;  in  which  case  there  was  the  whole 
number  of  persons  to  one,  which  I  think  was  three  or  four  hundred.  And  he  so  in- 
sured about  200  for  200  shillings,  so  that  he  could  not  have  lost  if  one  of  them  had 
drawn  it,  for  there  was  enough  to  pay  the  £10 ;  but  it  happened  another  drew  it,  and 
so  he  got  all  the  money  he  took  " ;  in  the  case  of  Davenant  v.  Midy  (1695-1696) 
House  of  Lords  MSS.  (N.S.)  ii  p.  196  no.  1009  there  is  mention  in  1695-1696  of  an 
appeal  to  the  House  (which  never  came  to  a  hearing)  which  turned  on  "  policies  of 
insurance  concerning  the  taking  or  not  taking  of  towns." 


CONCLUSIONS  299 

the  principles  which  civilians  and  canonists  had  for  centuries  been 
developing  from  a  basis  of  Roman  law.1  But,  from  the  point  of 
view  of  the  common  law,  the  absorption  of  this  new  domain  of 
commercial  law  was  absolutely  necessary  to  the  consolidation  of  its 
position  of  supremacy  in  the  state.  It  did  for  that  part  of  the 
common  law  which  was  concerned  with  private  relations,  what  the 
results  of  the  political  controversies  of  the  seventeenth  century  had 
done  for  that  part  of  it  which  was  concerned  with  public  law.  For 
just  as  the  results  of  those  political  controversies  had  made  it  the 
supreme  law  in  the  state,  so  this  absorption  of  the  domain  of  com- 
mercial law  gave  it  its  continued  supremacy  over  the  private  law 
of  the  future. 

Down  to  the  seventeenth  century  the  land  law  had  been  by  far 
the  most  important  branch  of  the  common  law.  The  common  law 
possessed  a  body  of  principles  applicable  to  this  part  of  the  law, 
which  were  both  more  numerous  and  worked  out  into  greater 
detail,  than  the  principles  applicable  to  any  other  part  of  the  law. 
The  broad  result  of  the  developments  related  in  this  chapter  was 
to  establish  commercial  law  as  a  rival  to  the  land  law — a  rival 
which  will  in  the  succeeding  centuries  oust  the  land  law  from  its 
old  positioa  But  this  result  will  not  be  accomplished  immediately. 
The  immediate  results  were  a  broadening  of  the  horizon  of  the 
common  lawyers,  and  a  consequent  willingness  to  receive  new 
ideas  and  new  points  of  view,  which  were  conditions  precedent  to 
the  continued  supremacy  of  a  law  which  claimed  to  guide  the  legal 
development  of  a  progressive  state.  Nor  are  these  results  surpris- 
ing. This  commercial  law  which  had  been  thus  received  into  the 
common  law  was  jus  gentium ;  and  its  reception  had  the  same 
results  upon  the  mediaeval  fabric  of  the  older  parts  of  the  common 
law,  as  the  reception  of  the  Roman  jus  gentium  of  the  peregrine 
praector  had  long  ago  had  upon  the  jus  civile. 

Already  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century  these  results 
had  begun  to  be  apparent.  We  cannot,  it  is  true,  say  that  they 
produced  much  direct  effect  upon  the  land  law.  That  law,  as  we 
have  seen,  continued  to  be  very  mediaeval  right  down  to  the 
reforms  of  the  nineteenth  century ;  and,  in  spite  of  those  reforms, 
it  still  bears  many  marks  of  the  fact  that  it  is  a  branch  of  our 
private  law  which  dates  from  that  feudal  period  when  it  was  much 
more  than  merely  private  law.  But  we  have  seen  that  the  new 
needs  and  new  ideas  of  this  age  had  left  their  marks  even  on  the 
land  law,  and  that  its  rules  were  being  adapted  to  the  new  needs 
of  landowners.  On  all  other  branches  of  the  common  law  the 
effect  of  the  ideas  which  came  with  this  new  commercial  jurisdic- 
tion is  beginning  to  be  directly  apparent.     We  have  seen  that  the 

1  Vol.  v  153-154 ;  vol.  vi  522. 


300  THE  LAW  MERCHANT 

result  of  Holt's  controversy  with  the  merchants  over  the  negotia- 
bility of  promissory  notes,  was  to  make  it  clear  that  the  lawyers 
must  adapt  their  technical  rules  to  the  needs  and  usages  of 
commerce ; x  and  the  manner  in  which  other  branches  of  the 
common  law  were  developing  show  that  the  lawyers  were  alive  to 
this  necessity.  We  have  already  seen  that  the  development  of 
the  law  of  bailment,2  of  the  conception  of  a  chose  in  action,3  and 
of  many  branches  of  the  law  of  contract,4  illustrate  this  fact ;  and 
that  it  is  to  a  small  extent  reflected  in  the  statutory  developments 
of  the  criminal  law  as  to  forgery,5  larceny,5  and  shipping.6  We 
shall  see  in  the  following  chapter  that  it  is  also  reflected  in  the 
developments  made  in  the  law  both  as  to  specific  torts,  and  in  the 
principles  of  liability  for  tort. 

1  Above  176.  2  Vol.  vii  432-433,  450-455,  461-463  ;  above  259. 

3  Vol.  vii  515  seqq.  4See  above  chap,  iii  §  2.  6Vol.  iv  501-503. 

6  Vol.  vi  400-401. 


CHAPTER  V 

CRIME  AND  TORT 

THREE  sets  of  influences  have  shaped  the  technical  develop- 
ment of  this  branch  of  the  law  during  this  period — the 
Legislature,  the  new  ideas  introduced  by  the  Council  and 
the  Star  Chamber,  and  the  doctrines  of  the  common  law.  I  have 
given  some  account  of  the  first1  and  second2  of  these  influences 
in  the  first  Part  of  this  Book.  In  this  chapter  I  shall  deal  mainly 
with  the  third  of  these  influences — the  doctrines  of  the  common 
law — and  show  how  these  doctrines,  as  both  expanded  and 
modified  by  the  first  two  of  these  influences,  have  created  our 
modern  law  of  crime  and  tort 

In  this,  as  in  the  mediaeval  period,3  the  influence  of  the 
Legislature  upon  the  growth  of  the  criminal  law  has  been  great. 
We  see  it  in  the  creation  of  new  statutory  treasons  either  to  meet 
particular  political  emergencies,  or  to  supplement  the  deficiencies 
of  Edward  III.'s  Statute  of  Treason.  We  see  it  no  less  in  the 
creation  of  various  new  felonies.  Some  of  these  were  intended  to 
supplement  the  law  of  treason  by  providing  a  more  severe  punish- 
ment for  such  offences  as  riots,  seditious  libels,  or  conspiracies. 
Others  were  directed  to  an  object  which,  at  this  period,  was  con- 
sidered to  be  closely  cognate  to  the  suppression  of  offences  akin 
to  treason — the  penalizing  of  dissent  from  the  national  church, 
whether  the  dissenter  was  a  Roman  Catholic,  a  Protestant,  or  an 
atheist  Others  created  new  or  extended  old  offences  against 
person  or  property.  Others  were  connected  with  that  long  series 
of  statutes  in  which  the  state  had  prescribed  its  policy  in  relation 
to  industry  and  commerce.4  Others  were  passed  to  penalize 
certain  forms  of  immorality,  which  the  weakness  of  the  ecclesiasti- 
cal courts  made  it  expedient  to  hand  over  to  the  common  law. 
And  the  activity  of  the  Legislature  was  not  exhausted  by  the 
creation  of  these  new  treasons  and  felonies.  We  have  seen  that 
this  period  is  marked  by  the  creation  of  many  new  crimes  below 
the  degree  of  felony.  These  "  misdemeanours "  are  definitely 
criminal  offences,  and  become  gradually  quite  distinct  from  those 

1  Vol.  iv  492-532  ;  vol.  vi.  399-407.  3  Vol.  v  167-214. 

3  Vol.  ii  449-453  ;  vol.  iii.  277.  4  Vol.  iv  314  seqq. ;  vol.  vi.  313  seqq. 

30I 


302  CRIME  AND  TORT 

quasi-criminal  trespasses  which  are  so  striking  a  feature  of  the 
mediaeval  common  law.1  They  are  either  less  serious  forms  of 
similar  offences  which  rank  as  felonies,  or  they  are  minor  forms  of 
wrongdoing,  which  are,  for  the  most  part,  matters  to  be  dealt 
with  by  the  justices  of  the  peace  sitting  in  their  petty  or  quarter 
sessions.  It  was  the  creation  of  these  misdemeanours  which  won 
back  to  the  field  of  criminal  law  many  forms  of  wrongdoing, 
which  the  emphasis  laid  in  the  Middle  Ages  on  the  civil  aspect  of 
trespass  had  tended  to  annex  to  the  field  of  tort. 

But  this  enlargement  of  the  field  of  criminal  law  was  not  due 
entirely  to  the  Legislature.  It  owed  at  least  as  much  to  the  new 
ideas  introduced  by  the  Council  and  the  Star  Chamber.  We  have 
seen  that  it  was  through  the  influence  of  the  procedure  of  the  Star 
Chamber  that  the  criminal  procedure  of  the  common  law  tended 
to  acquire  rules,  which,  by  giving  many  advantages  to  the  Crown, 
increased  the  strength  of  the  criminal  law.2  The  Star  Chamber 
also  materially  helped  the  development  of  the  law  as  to  riot,  and 
created  the  law  as  to  the  illegality  of  attempts  to  commit  crimes. 
It  added  important  new  elements  to  the  crime  of  conspiracy,  and  it 
created  the  crime  of  libel.  It  helped  to  enlarge  the  ideas  of  the 
common  law  as  to  fraud  ;  and  by  its  firm  action  in  regard  to  such 
offences  as  maintenance,  champerty,  and  embracery,  it  helped  to 
make  them  less  serious  menaces  to  the  proper  administration  of 
the  law,  and  thus  to  reduce  them  to  the  comparatively  unimpor- 
tant position  which  they  hold  in  modern  law.3 

Both  the  enlargement  of  the  criminal  law  by  the  Legislature, 
and  the  new  doctrines  of  the  court  of  Star  Chamber,  necessarily 
exercised  important  effects  upon  the  development  of  many 
common  law  doctrines  in  the  sphere  of  crime  and  tort.  But  in 
both  spheres  the  common  law  contributed  something  of  its  own. 
In  the  sphere  of  treason  we  shall  see  that  it  added  to  the  law  the 
doctrine  of  constructive  treason  ;  and  that  this  addition,  to  a  large 
extent,  rendered  unnecessary  those  statutory  extensions  of 
Edward  III.'s  statute,  which  were  so  frequently  made  during  the 
sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.4  In  the  sphere  of  felony  it 
developed  and  filled  up  the  somewhat  bare  outlines  of  the  mediaeval 
common  law  as  to  the  essentials  of  the  common  law  felonies.  One 
or  two  illustrations  of  this  process  will  indicate  the  manner  in 
which  the  rules  of  this  branch  of  the  modern  criminal  law  were 
built  up  on  the  basis  of  mediaeval  principles. 

The  readiness  with  which  all  classes  resorted  to  lethal  weapons 
to  assert  their  rights,  or  to  avenge  any  insult  real  or  fancied,  gave 
abundant  opportunity  for  elaborating  the  distinctions  between  the 

1  Vol.  iii  317-318,  370-371.  2  Vol.  v  188-196. 

3  Ibid  201-203.  4  Below  309-310. 


COMMON  LAW  FELONIES  303 

various  kinds  of  Iwmicide,  and,  in  particular,  the  distinction  between 
murder  and  manslaughter.1  Thus  it  was  ruled  in  1 553  -  that,  if  A 
set  on  B  intending  to  kill  him,  and  C  suddenly  intervened  in  the 
combat,  and  B  was  killed,  though  it  was  murder  in  A,  it  was  only 
manslaughter  in  C  ;  and,  it  would  seem  from  Plowden's  comment, 
that  this  ruling  settled  a  point  of  law  which  had  long  been  doubt- 
ful.3 In  1 61 2  it  was  ruled  that  if  a  man,  being  provoked,  in  hot 
blood  beat  another  with  a  weapon  not  likely  to  cause  death,  and 
it  did  cause  death,  he  was  only  guilty  of  manslaughter  ;  *  but  it 
was  held  in  1666  that  the  fact  that  there  was  provocation  would 
not  reduce  the  crime  from  murder  to  manslaughter,  if  the  accused 
had  used  a  weapon  likely  to  cause  death,5  a  decision  which  was 
approved  by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  1698. 6  On  the  question  what  would 
amount  to  a  provocation,  it  was  ruled  in  1666  that  mere  words 
would  not  be  an  adequate  provocation  for  homicide  ;  "  but  if 
upon  ill  words  both  parties  suddenly  fight,  and  one  kill  the  other, 
this  is  but  manslaughter,  for  it  is  a  combat  between  two  upon 
sudden  heat."  ~  But  other  cases  show  that  this  question  gave 
rise  to  many  difficult  questions  and  divisions  of  judicial  opinion.8 
In  cases  where  the  death  had  not  followed  immediately  upon, 
and  was  not  solely  occasioned  by,  the  stroke,  the  law  was  inclin- 
ing to  the  view  that  the  person  who  gave  the  stroke  was  guilty 
of  homicide ; 9  but  that  a  person  who,  without  using  physical 
violence,  had  occasioned  a  death  by  "  working  on  the  fancy  of 
another,"  or  by  unkind  or  harsh  usage,  which  was  not  ordinarily 
calculated  to  have  this  effect,  was  not  guilty.10     The  rules  as  to 

1  For  a  more  detailed  account  of  the  development  of  the  law  during  this  period 
see  Stephen,  H.C.L.  iii  46-73  ;  for  the  development  of  the  principles  of  criminal 
liability  in  relation  to  homicide  and  other  crimes  see  below  433-446. 

a  Points  ruled  at  the  sessions  held  at  Salop,  Plowden  at  p.  100. 

1 "  Quod  nota  bene  lector,  for  I  have  heard  this  greatly  doubted,  viz.  if  the 
master  lies  in  wait  in  the  highway  to  kill  a  man,  and  his  servants  attend  upon  him, 
and  the  master  does  not  make  his  servants  privy  to  his  intent,  and  afterwards  he,  for 
whom  the  master  lies  in  wait  comes,  and  the  master  attacks  him,  and  his  servants 
seeing  their  master  fighting,  take  his  part,  and  all  of  them  kill  the  man,  whether  or  no 
this  should  be  murder  in  the  servants.  .  .  .  But  this  is  by  the  above  rule  of  the  Court 
put  out  of  doubt,  viz.  that  it  shall  only  be  manslaughter  in  the  servants,"  ibid  at  p.  101. 

4  John  Royley's  Case,  Cro.  Jac.  296.  5  R.  v.  Grey  Kelyng  64-65. 

6  R.  v.  Keite,  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  144. 

7  Resolutions  preparatory  to  the  trial  of  Lord  Morley,  Kelyng  55. 

8  R.  v.  Huggett  (1666)  Kelyng  59-62  ;  the  whole  subject  was  fully  dealt  with  in 
the  elaborate  judgment  in  R.  v.  Mawgridge  (1707)  Kelyng  119  in  which  all  the  judges 
except  Trevor,  C.J.,  concurred ;  R.  v.  Oneby  (1727)  2  Ld.  Raym.  1485  ;  see  Stephen, 
H.C.L.  iii  70-73. 

9  Hale  P.C.  i  428-429.  "  This  hastening  of  the  death  (by  the  wound  or  stroke) 
is  homicide  or  murder  ...  in  him  that  gives  the  wound  or  hurt,  for  he  doth  not  die 
simply  ex  visitatione  Dei  .  .  .  and  an  offender  of  such  a  nature  shall  not  apportion 
his  own  wrong,  and  thus  I  have  often  heard  that  learned  and  wise  judge  justice  Rolle 
frequently  direct." 

10  "  In  foro  humano  it  cannot  come  under  the  judgment  of  felony  because  no  ex- 
ternal act  of  violence  was  offered  .  .  .  and  hence  it  was  that  before  the  statute  of 
j  Jac  cap.  12  (vol.  iv  510-511)  witch-craft  or  fascination  was  not  felony,"  ibid  429. 


304  CRIME  AND  TORT 

what  facts  would  prove  that  a  man  had  killed  another  by  misad- 
venture 1  or  se  defendendo  *2  were  being  elaborated.  Similarly  the 
cases  in  which  homicide  was  justifiable  were  restated ; 3  and  the 
construction  of  the  statute  of  1 532/  which  excused  from  guilt  those 
who  killed  persons  attempting  robbery  or  murder  in  or  near  the 
highway,  or  in  mansion  houses,  gave  rise  to  a  number  of  decisions 
as  to  the  cases  which  fell  within  its  protection.5  The  suicide  of 
Hales,  J.,  in  1554  gave  rise  to  a  restatement  of  the  rule  that  this 
form  of  homicide  was  murder,  because  it  was  ot  malice  propense  ;  6 
but  we  shall  see  that  it  was  during  this  period  that  the  lawyers 
were  beginning  to  develop  certain  constructive  extensions  of  this 
requirement  of  malice,  which  in  many  cases  gave  it  a  very 
artificial  meaning,  and  tended  to  render  very  technical  the  dis- 
tinctions between  the  different  forms  of  homicide.7 

The  inconvenience  caused  by  the  very  narrow  ground  covered 
by  larceny?  led  the  judges  to  widen  it  as  far  as  possible,  by  hold- 
ing that  a  very  small  physical  interference  with  the  property  would 
amount  to  an  asportation.9  The  differences  of  judicial  opinion  as 
to  whether  the  appropriation  of  the  bed  linen  by  a  lodger  in 
furnished  apartments  was  larceny,10  led,  as  we  have  seen,  to  a 
statute  which  declared  that  in  such  a  case  larceny  had  been  com- 
mitted ;  u  and  the  relations  both  of  husband  and  wife,  and  of  the 
co-owners  of  property,  led  to  some  difficulties  where  goods  were 
appropriated  by  a  wife  or  a  co-owner.12  In  the  case  of  robbery 
the  law  was  inclined  to  construe  somewhat  liberally  both  the  acts 
which  amounted  to  the  taking  of  property  by  "putting  in  fear," 
and  the  acts  which  amounted  to  "a  taking  from  the  person";13 
but  the  view  was  strictly  adhered  to  that  there  must  have  been  a 
taking,  and  that  the  taking  must  have  been  effected  by  violence  or 
putting  in  fear.14  It  was  during  this  period  that  the  essentials  of 
the  offence  of  burglary  were  precisely  ascertained.15  It  was  settled, 
after  some  conflict  of  opinion,  that  there  must  be  an  actual  break- 

1  Coke,  Third  Instit.  56 ;  R.  v.  Levett  (1640)  Cro.  Car.  at  p.  538. 

2  Hale,  P.C.  i  479-485. 

3  Vol.  iii  312;  Foxley's  Case  (1601)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  ff  109b,  110a. 

4  Vol.  iii  312  n.  3.  5  Hale,  P.C.  i  487-488. 
H  Hales  v.  Petit  (1563)  Plowden  at  p.  261  per  Dyer,  C.J. 

7  Below  435-437.  8Vol.  iii  361-366.  "Hale,  P.C.  i  508. 

10  R.  v.  Raven  (1662)  Kelyng  24 — held  not  to  be  larceny ;  but  this  decision  was 
doubted,  see  ibid  81-82 ;  Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  i  c.  33,  §  10. 
11 3  William  and  Mary  c.  g  §  5 ;  vol.  vi  402. 
12  Hale,  P.C.  i  513-514-  13  Ibid  i  532-533- 

14  See  the  case  of  R.  v.  Harman  (1620),  cited  Hale,  P.C.  i  534-535. 

15  Ibid  549-550.  I  stated,  vol.  iii  369,  that  for  the  rule  that  burglary  must  be 
committed  at  night  no  earlier  authority  than  a  case  of  Edward  VI. 's  reign  has  been 
cited ;  but  Marowe,  Reading,  Oxford  Studies  vii  378,  states  the  rule  as  an  essential 
part  of  the  offence.  It  is  possible  that  it  was  not  a  perfectly  well  settled  rule  when 
Marowe  wrote  in  1503 — though  he  states  it  as  such ;  and  that  the  sixteenth-century 
statutes,  cited  vol.  iii  369,  had  something  to  do  with  its  definite  settlement. 


MISDEMEANOUR  AND  TORT  305 

ing,  and  that  a  mere  breaking  in  law 1  was  not  sufficient.2  On 
the  other  hand,  an  entry  gained  under  false  pretences  in  order  to 
commit  a  felony,  was  a  sufficient  breaking,3  and  so  was  the  break- 
ing of  an  inner  door  by  one  who  had  come  in  through  an  open  door 
or  window.4  In  the  case  of  arson  we  have  seen  that  it  was 
settled  in  this  period  that  a  man  who  had  burned  his  own  house 
was  not  guilty  of  this  crime.5 

The  distinctions  between  principals  in  the  first  and  second 
degree,  and  between  principals  and  accessories  were  elucidated 
by  their  application  to  the  facts  of  various  cases ; G  and  we  shall 
see  that  the  principles  of  criminal  liability  established  in  the 
Middle  Ages  were  elaborated,  and  in  some  respects  modified." 

The  enlargement  of  the  sphere  of  misdemeanour  during  this 
period  was  due  rather  to  the  action  of  the  Legislature  8  and  the 
Star  Chamber,9  than  to  the  action  of  the  common  law.  But  the 
common  law  showed  a  tendency  to  follow  this  lead,  and  to  hold 
that  obvious  wrongs,  which  did  not  amount  to  felonies,  were  mis- 
demeanours. Thus  in  Holmes's  Case  the  court  held  that  the 
offence  of  burning  one's  own  house,  though  it  did  not  amount  to 
arson,  was  a  misdemeanour  punishable  by  fine  and  imprisonment.1" 
In  this  period,  however,  as  in  the  mediaeval  period,11  it  is  in  the 
sphere  of  tort,  rather  than  in  the  sphere  of  crime,  that  the  common 
law  made  its  most  important  contribution  to  the  law  as  to  wrongs 
under  the  degree  of  felony.  We  have  seen  that,  even  in  the 
mediaeval  period,  there  were  some  signs  that  new  developments 
were  beginning  in  this  sphere ;  and  that  the  means  by  which 
these  developments  will  be  made  will  be  a  liberal  use  of  the 
action  on  the  case.12  All  through  this  period  this  development 
proceeded  rapidly.  It  followed,  firstly,  that  certain  rules  applic- 
able to  certain  specific  torts  began  to  be  developed,  with  the  result 
that  these  torts  began  to  assume  their  modern  characteristics  ;  and, 
secondly,  that  the  mediaeval  principles  of  civil  liability  began  to 
be  added  to  and  modified. 


1 "  Everyone  that  enters  into  another's  house  against  his  will  or  to  commit  a 
felony,  tho'  the  doors  be  open,  doth  in  law  break  the  house,"  Hale,  P.C.  i  551. 

8 "  And  altho'  in  the  remembrance  of  some  yet  alive  Sir  Nicholas  Hide  chief 
justice  did  hold  that  a  breaking  in  law  was  sufficient  to  make  a  burglary  .  .  .  yet  the 
law  is  that  a  bare  breaking  in  law  ...  is  not  sufficient  to  make  a  burglary  without 
an  actual  breaking,"  ibid  i  551-552. 

3  Kelyng  42-43 ;  cp.  R.  v.  Cassy  and  Cotter  (1666)  ibid  62-63. 

4  R.  v.  Cassy  and  Cotter,  Kelyng  62-63 ;  R-  v.  Johnson  (1666)  ibid  58-59 ;  it  was 
held  in  the  last  cited  case  that  if  no  door  had  been  broken,  but  only  a  trunk  or  box, 
the  offence  did  not  amount  to  burglary. 

5  Vol.  iii  370  n.  7. 

e(I553)  Plowden  97-98;  Kelyng  52-53;  Hale,  P.C.  i  615-618;  vol.  iii  307-310. 
7  Below  433-446.  8Vol.  iv  512-521;  vol.  vi  402-405. 

9  Vol.  v  197-214.  10(i635)  Cro.  Car.  376. 

"Vol.  iii  318,  370-371.  ^Ibid  406-407,  407-411. 

VOL.  VIII.— 20 


30G  CRIME  AND  TORT 

But,  in  certain  cases,  the  development  of  the  law  relating  to 
those  wrongs,  which  hover  on  the  border  line  of  crime  and  tort, 
was  complicated  by  the  two  somewhat  different  streams  of  doctrine, 
which  originated  in  the  courts  of  common  law  and  in  the  Star 
Chamber.  When  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Star  Chamber  was 
abolished,  many  of  the  doctrines  which  it  had  developed  were 
taken  over  by  the  common  law  courts.  These  courts  were  there- 
fore obliged  to  co-ordinate  and  reconcile  these  divergent  streams 
of  doctrine.  No  doubt  the  common  law  was  enriched  by  the 
reception  of  these  new  ideas.  But  they  tended  to  produce  a 
development  of  the  law  which  was  not  altogether  harmonious,  or 
altogether  convenient ;  and  we  shall  see  that  its  results  are  plainly 
visible  to-day  in  such  branches  of  the  law  as  defamation l  and 
conspiracy.2  In  particular,  it  tended  to  obscure  still  further  the 
line  between  crime  and  tort.  In  the  Middle  Ages  and  later,  the 
double  nature  of,  and  the  wide  field  covered  by  trespass  and  its 
offshoots,  effectually  prevented  any  real  distinction  between  tort 
and  crime,  based  upon  the  nature  of  the  act  done.3  In  this 
period,  the  fact  that  the  Star  Chamber  treated  certain  acts  as 
criminal,  while  the  common  law  courts  remedied  the  same  or 
similar  acts  by  a  civil  action  on  the  case  for  damages,  made  it 
more  impossible  than  ever  to  draw  any  distinction  on  these  lines. 
"  If,"  says  Professor  Kenny,4  "we  know  any  particular  occurrence 
to  be  a  crime,  it  is  easy  to  ascertain  whether  or  not  it  is  also  a 
tort,  by  asking  if  it  damages  any  assignable  individual.  But 
there  is  no  corresponding  test  whereby,  when  we  know  an  oc- 
currence to  be  a  tort,  we  can  readily  ascertain  whether  or  not  it 
is  also  a  crime.  We  cannot  go  beyond  the  rough  historical 
generalization  that  torts  have  been  erected  into  crimes,  whenever 
the  law-making  power  had  come  to  regard  the  mere  civil  remedy 
for  them  as  being  inadequate," 

The  only  certain  lines  of  distinction  are  to  be  found  in  the 
nature  of  the  remedy  given,  and  the  nature  of  the  procedure  to 
enforce  that  remedy.  If  the  remedy  given  is  compensation, 
damages,  or  a  penalty  enforced  by  a  civil  action,  the  wrong  so 
redressed  is  a  civil  wrong.  If  the  remedy  given  is  the  punish- 
ment of  the  accused,  which  is  enforced  by  a  prosecution  at  the 
suit  of  the  crown,  the  wrong  so  redressed  is  a  crime  or  criminal  in 
its  nature.5  Even  this  test  sometimes  fails  to  establish  a  clear 
line  of  difference.6 

The  need  to  adjust  the  doctrines  of  the  mediaeval   criminal 

1  Below  361-367.  2  Below  379-384,  392-394. 

3  Vol.  iii  317-318,  370-371.  4  Outlines  of  Criminal  Law,  20-21. 

5  See  the  classification  of  the  various  kinds  of  proceedings  which  may  be  taken 
against  wrongdoers  in  Kenny,  op.  cit.  16-17. 

6  See  Attorney-General  v.  Bradlaugh  (T885)  14  Q.B.D.  667. 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  307 

law  to  their  new  environment  in  the  modern  state ;  the  need  to 
modify,  to  enlarge,  and  to  elaborate  the  law  of  tort  and  the  prin- 
ciples of  civil  liability,  to  meet  the  new  demands  caused  by  the 
more  varied  and  complex  life  of  such  a  state ;  and  the  need  to 
adjust  and  to  harmonize  the  two  similar  yet  divergent  lines  of 
doctrine,  which,  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries, 
were  being  simultaneously  developed  by  the  common  law  courts 
and  the  Star  Chamber — all  had  their  influence  on  the  technical 
development  of  many  of  the  rules  of  the  law  of  crime  and  tort. 
One  or  other  of  these  causes  is  historically  at  the  root  of  the 
most  salient  of  these  developments  during  this  period.  With 
these  developments  I  shall  deal  in  this  chapter  under  the  follow- 
ing heads: — £  i.  Constructive  Treason  and  other  Cognate  Offences; 
§  2.  Defamation ;  §  3.  Conspiracy,  Malicious  Prosecution,  and 
Maintenance ;  §  4.  Legal  Doctrines  Resulting  from  the  Laws 
against  Religious  Nonconformity ;  §  5.  Lines  of  Future  Develop- 
ment ;  §  6.   The  principles  of  Liability. 

§  1.  Constructive  Treason  and  other  Cognate 
Offences 

Constructive  Treason 

The  three  clauses  of  Edward  III.'s  Statute  of  Treason  which 
are  designed  to  protect  the  safety  of  the  state,  are  the  clauses 
which  make  it  treason  to  compass  or  imagine  the  king's  death, 
to  levy  war  against  the  king,  and  to  adhere  to  his  enemies.1 

The  last  of  these  clauses  can  be  briefly  dismissed.  It  has  not 
been  extended  by  construction  in  the  same  way  as  the  first  two 
clauses.  The  only  difficulty  which  has  arisen  in  connection  with 
it  has  been  the  difficulty  of  deciding  whether  adherence  to  the 
king's  enemies  out  of  the  realm  is  included  in  it.2  This  difficulty 
arises  solely  from  the  wording  of  the  clause,  which  enacts  that  it 
shall  be  treason,  "  if  a  man  do  levy  war  against  our  Lord  the 
King  in  his  realm  or  be  adherent  to  the  king's  enemies  in  his 
realm  giving  to  them  aid  and  comfort  in  the  realm  or  elsewhere."3 
This  clause  might  be  construed  to  mean  that  the  words  "  or  else- 
where "  govern  only  the  words  "  giving  to  them  aid  or  comfort," 
so  that  adhering  to  the  king's  enemies  outside  the  realm  is  not 
treason;  or  it  might  be  construed  to  mean  that  the  words  "or 

1  For  this  statute  see  vol.  ii  449-450  ;  vol.  iii  287-293. 

2  All  the  authorities  on  this  subject  are  collected  in  R.  v  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B. 
98. 

3  "  Si  homme  leve  de  guerre  contre  notre  dit  Seigneur  le  Roi  en  son  Roialme  ou 
soit  aherdant  as  enemys  notre  Seigneur  le  Roi  en  le  Roialme  donant  a  eux  eid  ou 
contort  en  son  Roialme  ou  per  aillours." 


308  CRIME  AND  TORT 

elsewhere"  govern  the  whole  clause,  so  that  adhering  to  the 
king's  enemies,  and  it  would  seem  also  the  levying  of  war,1  out- 
side the  kingdom  are  treason.2  It  would  seem  from  the  pre- 
cedents cited  by  Hale  that,  before  the  statute,  adhering  to  the 
king's  enemies  outside  the  kingdom  was  treason ; 3  and  it  seems 
to  have  been  assumed  that  the  statute  had  not  altered  the  law. 
This  is  reasonably  clear  from  a  dictum  in  a  case  of  1 382,  in  which 
it  was  laid  down  that,  if  a  man  adhered  to  the  king's  enemies  in 
France,  "his  adherence  shall  be  tried  where  his  land  is,  as  has 
been  often  done  of  adherents  to  the  enemies  of  the  king  in  Scot- 
land."4 If  he  had  no  land,  Hale  thought  that  he  might  be  tried 
in  any  county  in  England,  which  is  by  no  means  improbable.5 
No  doubt  there  was  some  difficulty  as  to  the  trial  of  persons  who 
had  thus  committed  treason  out  of  the  kingdom,  owing  to  the 
difficulties  arising  from  the  rules  of  venue.6  But  we  have  seen 
that  this  difficulty  was  removed  by  the  statute  of  1  543-1  544  ; 7  and 
the  wording  of  that  statute  makes  it  clear  enough  that,  in  the 
opinion  of  the  Legislature,  acts  committed  abroad  might  amount 
to  treason.8  It  follows,  therefore,  that  Coke,9  Hale,10  and  Haw- 
kins u  were  well  warranted  in  holding  that  adhering  to  the  king's 
enemies  outside  the  kingdom  was  an  offence  which  came  within 
the  scope  of  Edward  III.'s  statute.  Later  cases  have  all  laid 
down  the  law  in  the  same  way  ; n  and,  after  an  elaborate  review 
of  the  authorities,  this  interpretation  was  finally  established  as 
correct  in  191 6  in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Casement. 

It  is  the  first  two  of  these  three  clauses  of  the  statute,  and 
especially  the  first,  which  have  been  widely  extended  by  judicial 
construction.      I  shall  deal  firstly  with  the  clause  as  to  compassing 

1  There  seems  to  be  no  authority  on  the  question  whether  levying  of  war  out  of 
the  realm  is  treason;  but  the  reasoning  of  R.  v.  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B.  98,  and  the 
authorities  on  which  that  decision  is  based,  clearly  apply;  on  the  other  hand,  Coke, 
Third  Instit.  9,  and  Hale,  P.C.  i  130,  154-158,  seem  to  say  that  the  levying  of  war  must 
be  in  the  realm ;  and  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  269,  takes  this  view. 

2  R.  v.  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B.  at  p.  122  per  Lord  Reading,  C.J. 

3  Case  of  Poynter,  Claus.  7  Ed.  III.  part  1  m.  9,  Hale,  P.C.  i  166  ;  case  of  Culwin 
Clans.  7  Ed.  III.  part  1  m.  15,  ibid  167-168. 

4  Fitz.  Ab.  Trial  pi.  54 — "  Si  home  soit  adherent  as  enemys  le  roi  en  Fraunce  sa 
terre  est  forfetable,  sa  adherauns  serra  trei  lou  sa  terre  est  come  ad  este  souvent  foitz 
fait  des  adherauntz  as  enemies  le  Roy  en  Escoce  "  ;  the  translation  is  taken  from  the 
note  to  R.  v.  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B.  145. 

5  P.C.  i  170.  6  For  these  rules  see  vol.  v  117-ng,  140-143. 

7  35  Henry  VIII.  c.  2 ;  vol.  iv  524. 

8  See  R.  v.  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B.  at  p.  124  per  Lord  Reading,  C.J. 

»  Third  Instit.  10-11.  10  P.C.  I.  cap.  xv.  »  P.C.  Bk.  ii.  cap.  xxv  §  46. 

12  See  the  cases  cited  in  R.  v.  Casement  [1917]  1  K.B.  at  p.  128;  the  opinion  of 
the  law  officers  in  1775,  cited  ibid  at  p.  143  ;  Mulcahy  v.  R.  (1868)  L.R.  3  H.  of  L. 
at  p.  318 ;  R.  v.  Lynch  [1903]  1  K.B.  444  ;  note  also  that  in  R.  v.  Vaughan  (1696)  13 
S.T.  at  p.  525  Holt,  C.J.,  laid  it  down  quite  generally  that,  "  for  a  subject  of  England 
to  join  with  the  king's  enemies,  in  pursuit  of  a  design  to  burn  or  take  any  of  the 
king's  or  his  subjects'  ships,  that  is  an  adherence  to  the  king's  enemies." 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  309 

or  imagining  the  king's  death,  secondly  with  the  clause  as  to  levy- 
ing of  war  against  the  king,  and  thirdly  with  the  later  history  of 
this  branch  of  the  law. 

(i)  Compassing  or  imagining  the  king's  death. 

The  act  made  treason  by  the  statute  of  Edward  III.  is  not  the 
killing  of  the  king,  but  the  compassing  or  imagining  his  death — 
the  intention  to  kill  him.1  Therefore  in  1660  the  judges  resolved 
that  the  regicides  should  be  indicted  for  compassing ;  and  that  the 
actual  murder  of  the  king  "  should  be  made  use  of  as  one  of  the 
overt  acts  to  prove  the  compassing  of  his  death."  2  Even  in  the 
mediaeval  period,  the  judges  had  seen  that  the  fact  that  the  gist 
of  the  offence  was  an  intention  to  kill  the  king,  could  be  used  to 
extend  its  scope ;  for  they  had  held  that  the  mere  speaking  of 
words  might  be  an  overt  act  which  evidenced  such  an  intention.3 
They  had  seen  as  clearly  as  their  successors  that  such  an  intention 
can  be  proved  only  by  overt  acts,  "  for  the  thought  of  man  is  not 
triable"  ;  and  that  the  statute  could  be  extended  by  inferring  an 
intention  to  kill  from  overt  acts  which  were  only  remotely  con- 
nected, if  they  were  connected  at  all,  with  a  formed  intention  to 
kill  the  king.  But  these  cases  were  not  followed.  The  modern 
construction  of  this  clause,  though  it  started  from  somewhat  similar 
premises,  was  elaborated  under  a  different  set  of  legal  and  political 
conditions,  and,  unlike  these  mediaeval  constructions,  it  resulted 
in  the  establishment  of  a  definite  body  of  legal  doctrine. 

The  Tudor  kings  respected  the  law ;  and  they  were  well  aware 
that  nothing  could  be  more  dangerous  to  the  security  of  their  none 
too  secure  throne  than  any  attempt  to  pervert  it  It  was  for  this 
reason  that,  during  the  first  sixty  or  seventy  years  of  the  sixteenth 
century,  many  statutes  were  passed  to  extend  the  scope  of  treason,4 
and  that  very  little  is  heard  of  any  constructive  extension  of  this 
clause  of  Edward  III.'s  statute.  Hale,  commenting  on  the  statute 
of  1 540-1 541,  which  made  certain  riots  treason,  remarks  that  it 
shows,  "how  careful  they  were  in  this  time  not  to  be  overhasty  in 
introducing  constructive  treasons,  and  to  shew  how  the  opinions  of 
the  parliaments  of  Edward  VI.,  queen  Mary,  queen  Elizabeth  went, 
as  to  the  point  of  constructive  treason,  and  how  careful  they  were 
not  to  go  far  in  extending  the  statute  of  25  E.  3  beyond  the  letter 

1  Vol.  iii  292-293. 

2  "  It  was  resolved  that  the  indictments  should  be  for  compassing  the  death  of  the 
late  king  (the  very  compassing  and  imagining  the  king's  death,  being  the  treason 
within  the  stat.  25  Ed.  3)  and  then  that  we  might  lay  as  many  overt  acts  as  we  would,  to 
prove  the  compassing  of  his  death  :  but  it  was  agreed,  the  actual  murder  of  the  king 
should  be  precisely  laid  in  the  indictment,  with  the  special  circumstances  as  it  was 
done,  and  should  be  made  use  of  as  one  of  the  overt  acts,  to  prove  the  compassing  of 
his  death,"  Kelyng  8. 

3  Vol.  iii  293.  *  Vol.  iv  492-498. 


310  CRIME  AND  TORT 

thereof." 1  The  repeal  of  the  new  treasons  created  by  Henry  VI II. 
on  the  accession  of  Edward  VI.,  and  the  repeal  of  Edward  VI. 's 
statutes  on  the  accession  of  Mary,2  show  that  the  creation  of  new 
treasons,  even  by  Parliament,  was  not  a  popular  exploit.  It  could 
hardly  be  expected,  therefore,  that  the  courts  would  undertake 
their  manufacture. 

But,  though  there  was  always  a  tendency  to  revert  to  the 
statute  of  Edward  III.,  it  was  abundantly  clear  that  that  statute 
was  wholly  inadequate  to  protect  the  state.  The  Legislatures 
which  repealed  Henry  VIII.'s  and  Edward  VI.'s  statutes  were 
always  obliged  to  re-enact  some  of  the  provisions  of  those  statutes.3 
The  result  was  that,  by  Elizabeth's  reign,  the  nation  had  begun  to 
grow  accustomed  to  the  necessity  for  an  extended  law  of  treason, 
and  to  acquiesce  in  it.  This  changed  attitude  was  due,  not  only 
to  the  existence  of  these  statutes,  but  also  to  two  other  causes.  In 
the  first  place,  the  modern  territorial  state  was  now  well  established. 
It  was  coming  to  be  generally  recognized  that  allegiance  to  the 
state  ought  to  override  all  other  ties.  Hence  it  was  realized  that 
the  statute  was,  as  Stephen  has  said,  "  worded  too  narrowly  if  it 
was  to  be  construed  literally."4  In  the  second  place,  the  dangers 
to  the  queen's  life  from  the  constant  Roman  Catholic  plots,  and 
the  certainty  that  possibly  the  existence  of  the  English  state,  and 
certainly  its  orderly  development,  were  bound  up  with  her  safety, 
led  the  nation  to  acquiesce  in  any  measures  that  could  be  devised 
to  preserve  it.  Hence  the  constructive  extensions  of  this  clause 
of  the  statute  came  to  be  not  only  acquiesced  in,  but  even  approved 
as  necessary  means  of  defence  in  a  time  of  national  emergency. 
Under  these  circumstances,  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  it  was 
in  the  latter  part  of  the  sixteenth  century,  that  the  constructive 
extension  of  this  clause  of  the  statute  began  to  be  made. 

It  would  seem  that,  even  before  this  date,  the  Legislature  was 
aware  that  the  vagueness  of  Edward  III.'s  statute  made  the  exact 
content  of  its  clauses  by  no  means  certain.  Hale,  while  admitting 
that  it  was  "a  fair  topical  argument,"  that  the  offences  made 
treasons  by  new  and  temporary  Acts  were  not  treasons  within 
Edward  III.'s  statute,  yet  points  out  that  it  is  by  no  means  con- 
clusive ;  for  some  of  these  new  treasons  turned  out  to  be  within 
that  statute ;  and  certain  statutes  which  made  offences  felonies 
"have  this  wary  clause,  'the  same  not  being  treason  within  the 
statute  of  25  E.  3."'5     The  vagueness  of  the  statute  helped  the 

1  P.C.  i  293.  a  vol.  iv  495.  »  Ibid.  *  H.C.L.  ii  263. 

5  "  That  tho'  generally  it  be  a  fair  topical  argument,  that  when  offences  are  made 
treasons  by  new  and  temporary  Acts,  they  were  not  treasons  within  the  statute  of 
25  E.  3,  for  if  they  were,  they  needed  not  to  have  been  enacted  to  be  treason  by  new 
statutes,  as  introductive  of  new  laws  in  such  cases,  yet  that  doth  not  hold  universally 
true,  for  some  things  are  enacted  to  be  treason  by  new,  yea,  and  temporary  laws, 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  311 

judges  to  extend  it ;  but,  as  I  have  already  pointed  out,  the  fact 
that  it  was  the  intention  to  kill  the  king,  and  not  his  murder,  which 
was  made  treason,  was  the  main  reason  why  this  clause  could  be 
so  extensively  construed.  As  we  shall  now  see,  the  construction 
put  upon  it  grew  gradually  more  and  more  extensive,  till  it  came 
to  include  much  of  the  ground  covered  by  the  clauses  relating  to 
the  levying  of  war  against  the  king  and  adhering  to  his  enemies.1 

It  is  obvious  that  an  intention  to  kill  the  king  must  be  proved 
from  overt  acts,  which  show  that  the  person  doing  them  had  such 
an  intention.  "  This  compassing,  intent,  or  imagination,"  says 
Coke,2  "though  secret  is  .  .  .  to  be  discovered  by  circumstances 
precedent,  concomitant,  and  subsequent"  Now  it  is  clear  that  it 
is  only  from  overt  acts,  which  obviously  point  to  a  design  to  kill 
the  king,  that  an  intention  to  kill  him  can  properly  be  inferred. 
But  the  judges,  in  considering  overt  acts  alleged  to  prove  this  in- 
tention, did  not  limit  themselves  to  overt  acts  of  this  kind.  They 
considered  the  overt  acts  of  the  accused  "  with  all  endeavour  for 
the  safety  of  the  king."  3  Therefore  they  were  led  to  rule  that 
acts  which  showed  an  intention,  not  to  kill  him,  but  to  put  any 
kind  of  restraint  or  force  upon  him,  might  be  good  evidence  of  an 
intention  to  kill  him. 

We  can  see  the  doctrine  in  its  initial  stage  in  Coke's  Third 
Institute.  Treason,  he  says,  must  be  proved  by  an  overt  act,  "  as 
if  divers  do  conspire  the  death  of  the  king,  and  the  manner  how, 
and  thereupon  provide  weapons,  powder,  poison,  assay  harness, 
send  letters,  etc.,  or  the  like,  for  execution  of  the  conspiracy. 
Also  preparation  by  some  overt  act  to  depose  the  king  or  to  take 
the  king  by  force  and  strong  hand,  and  so  imprison  him  till  he 
hath  yielded  to  certain  demands,  this  is  a  sufficient  overt  act  to 
prove  the  compassing  and  imagination  of  the  death  of  the  king : 
for  this  upon  the  matter  is  to  make  the  king  a  subject,  and  to 
dispoil  him  of  his  kingly  office  of  royal  government.  And  so  it 
was  resolved  by  all  the  judges  of  England,  Hil.  I  Jac.  Regis,  in  the 
case  of  Ld.  Cobham,  Lord  Gray,  and  Watson  and  Clark,  seminary 
priests :  And  so  had  it  been  resolved  by  the  justices  Hil.  43  Eliz. 
in  the  case  of  the  earls  Essex  and  Southampton,  who  intended  to 
go  to  the  court  where  the  queen  was,  and  to  have  taken  her  into 
their  power,  and  to  have  removed  divers  of  her  counsel,  and  for 
that  end  did  assemble  a  multitude  of  people ;  this  being  raised  to 
the  end  aforesaid  was  a  sufficient  overt  act  for  compassing  the  death 
of  the  queen.     And  so  by  woeful  experience  in  former  times  it 

which  yet  were  treason  by  the  statute  of  25  E.  3,  as  will  appear  in  the  sequel.  And 
therefore  the  statutes  of  1,  2  Ph.  and  M.  cap.  3,  1  E.  6  cap.  12,  23  Eliz.  cap.  2, 
making  several  offences  felony,  have  this  wary  clause,  the  same  not  being  treason 
within  the  statute  of  25  E.  3,"  Hale,  P.C.  i  261. 

1  Below  314-318.  3  Third  Instit  6.  '  Coke,  ibid  6. 


312  CRIME  AND  TORT 

has  fallen  out  in  the  cases  of  Ed.  2,  R.  2,  H.  6,  and  E.  V.  that 
were  taken  and  imprisoned  by  their  subjects."  1  Similarly,  "if  a 
subject  conspire  with  a  foreign  prince  beyond  the  seas  to  invade 
the  realm  by  open  hostility,  and  prepare  for  the  same  by  some 
overt  act,  this  is  a  sufficient  overt  act  for  the  death  of  the  king."  2 
And,  if  such  overt  acts  were  advocated  in  a  published  book,  the 
writing  and  publication  of  such  a  book  was  an  overt  act  of  com- 
passing.3 Further,  Coke  decided  in  R.  v.  Owen^  that  saying  that 
the  king,  being  excommunicated  by  the  Pope,  may  lawfully  be 
deposed  and  killed  by  any  whatsoever,  and  that  such  killing  was 
not  murder,  was  treason.  Though,  as  we  shall  see,  Coke  held  that 
merely  speaking  scandalous  words  of  the  king  was  not  treason,  he 
was  of  opinion  that  words  which,  to  use  Bacon's  phrase,  "disabled 
the  king's  title,"  5  and  a  fortiori  words  which  incited  to  his  murder, 
were  an  overt  act  which  proved  the  compassing  of  his  death. 

Clearly  in  Coke's  day  the  constructive  extension  of  this  clause 
of  the  statute  had  begun.  That  it  had  begun  was  due  largely  to 
the  political  conditions  prevailing  in  England  and  Europe.  Coke's 
illustrations  make  this  clear.  All  the  acts  ruled  to  be  overt  acts 
proving  a  compassing  of  the  king's  death  were  obviously  dangerous 
to  him,  and  might  easily  lead  to  his  death  ;  and  this  was  especially 
true  in  Elizabeth's  reign,  when  the  fate  of  the  Reformation  seemed 
at  times  almost  to  depend  upon  her  life.  But  this  constructive 
extension  had  not  as  yet  gone  very  far ;  and  neither  Coke  nor 
most  of  his  colleagues  were  prepared  to  push  it  much  further. 
Thus,  firstly,  Coke  was  of  opinion  that  mere  scandalous  words  of 
the  king,  importing  that  he  was  unfit  to  reign,  unless  they  were 
words  which  disabled  his  title,  were  not  an  overt  act  from  which  a 
compassing  of  his  death  could  be  inferred — "  it  is  commonly  said 
that  bare  words  may  make  a  heretick,  but  not  a  traytor  without 
an  overt  act  "  ; 6  and  this  was  agreed  to  be  law  by  all  the  judges 
in  Pines  Case  in  1629,7  after  an  exhaustive  survey  of  the  earlier 
precedents.      Some  of  the  mediaeval  precedents,  it  is  true,  pointed 

1  Third  Instit.  12.  2  Ibid  14. 

3  "  Cardinal  Poole  ...  in  his  book  of  the  supremacy  of  the  Pope,  written  about 
27  H.  8,  incited  Charles  the  Emperor,  then  preparing  against  the  Turk,  to  bend  his 
force  against  his  natural  sovereign  lord  and  country  ;  the  writing  of  which  book  was 
a  sufficient  overt  act  within  this  statute,"  ibid  14. 

*  (1616)  1  Rolle  Rep.  185. 

5Spedding,  Letters  and  Life  of  Bacon  v  109. 

6  Third  Instit.  14. 

7  Cro.  Car.  117 — "  the  speaking  of  the  words  before  mentioned,  though  they  were 
as  wicked  as  might  be,  were  not  treason.  For  they  resolved  that  unless  it  were  by 
some  particular  statute,  no  words  will  be  treason  ;  for  there  is  no  treason  at  this  day 
but  by  the  statute  25  Edw.  3  c.  2  for  imagining  the  death  of  the  king  etc.,  and  the  in- 
dictment must  be  framed  upon  one  of  the  points  in  that  statute  ;  and  the  words  spoken 
here  can  be  but  evidence  to  discover  the  corrupt  heart  of  him  that  spake  them  ;  but  of 
themselves  they  are  not  treason,  neither  can  any  indictment  be  framed  upon  them." 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  313 

in  the  opposite  direction ;  and  some  lawyers,  including  Bacon,1 
would  have  liked  to  follow  them.  But  probably  the  judges  were 
influenced  by  the  wording  of  the  statutes  which  had,  in  the  pre- 
ceding reigns,  created  new  treasons.  In  many  cases  treasonable 
words  had  been  made  only  a  misdemeanour  for  the  first  offence, 
which  shows,  as  Hale  points  out,2  that,  in  the  opinion  of  the 
Legislature,  "  words,  tho'  of  an  high  nature,  were  not  treason,  nor 
an  overt  act  of  compassing  the  king's  death."  Secondly,  though, 
as  we  have  seen,  Coke  agreed  that  treasonable  words  set  down  in 
writing  and  published  were  an  overt  act  of  treason  by  compassing 
the  king's  death,3  in  Peachanis  Case*  neither  he,  nor  many  of  the 
other  judges,  could  be  persuaded  that  the  writing  of  treasonable 
words  in  a  sermon,  which  was  never  preached  or  published,  nor 
intended  to  be  preached  or  published,  was  treason.5  No  doubt 
opinion  was  divided  on  this  point ; 6  but  Peacham,  though  found 
guilty,  was  not  executed.  It  would  seem  that  Coke  regarded  such 
an  unpublished  document  as  being  equivalent  to  mere  words,  or 
perhaps,  as  they  were  not  published,  as  even  less  heinous.  Thirdly, 
Coke  laid  it  down  that  a  mere  conspiracy  to  levy  war  was  "no 
overt  act  to  or  manifest  proof  of  the  compassing  of  the  death  of  the 
king  within  this  Act,"  on  the  somewhat  inconclusive  ground  that 
so  to  hold  would  confound  the  several  clauses  of  the  statute.7 

These  limitations  upon  the  constructive  extension  of  this 
clause  of  the  Act  were  not  wholly  logical.  They  were,  as  I  have 
said,  largely  the  product  of  the  political  conditions  of  the  day ; 
and  it  is  clear  that  they  were  distasteful  to  the  crown  lawyers  of 
James  I.'s  reign.  Bacon,  in  his  conference  with  Coke  on  Peacham  s 
Case,  contended  that  "there  be  four  means  or  manners  whereby 
the  death  of  the  king  is  compassed  or  imagined.  The  first  by 
some  particular  fact  or  plot  The  second  by  disabling  his  title  ; 
as  by  affirming  that  he  is  not  lawful  king,  or  that  another  ought 
to  be  king,  or  that  he  is  an  usurper  or  a  bastard,  or  the  like.     The 

1  Spedding,  Letters  and  Life  of  Bacon  v  109,  120  ;  cp.  vi  92-93. 

2  P.C.  i  315  ;  and  cp.  his  comment  on  1,  2  Phillip  and  Mary  c.  3  at  p.  312. 

3  Above  312  and  n.  3. 

••(1615)  Cro.  Car.  125  ;  Spedding,  Letters  and  Life  of  Bacon  v  127. 

5  "  Edward  Peacham  was  indicted  of  treason  for  divers  treasonable  passages  in  a 
a  sermon  which  was  never  preached,  or  intended  to  be  preached,  but  only  set  down 
in  writings,  and  found  in  his  study ;  he  was  tried  and  found  guilty,  but  not  executed. 
Note,  that  many  of  the  judges  were  of  opinion  that  it  was  not  treason,"  Cro.  Car.  125. 

6  Thus  Chamberlain,  writing  to  Carleton  Feb.  20,  1614,  says,  "  the  king  since  his 
coming  hath  had  the  opinion  of  the  judges  severally  in  Peacham's  Case,  and  it  is  said 
that  most  of  them  concur  to  find  it  treason.  Yet  the  lord  chief  justice  is  for  the  con- 
trary," cited  Spedding,  op.  cit,  v  121  n. ;  for  James's  own  view  that  Peacham  was 
guilty  of  treason  see  ibid  105-106. 

7  "  One  of  them  (i.e.  the  different  treasons  set  out  in  the  Act)  cannot  be  an  overt 
act  for  another.  As  for  example  :  a  conspiracy  is  had  to  levy  war,  this  (as  hath  been 
said  and  so  resolved)  is  no  treason  by  this  Act  until  it  be  levied,  therefore  it  is  no 
overt  act  or  manifest  proof  of  the  compassing  of  the  death  of  the  king  within  this  Act 
...  for  this  were  to  confound  the  several  clauses, "  Third  Instit.  14. 


314  CRIME  AND  TORT 

third  by  subjecting  his  title ;  as  either  to  pope  or  people ;  and 
thereby  making  him  of  an  absolute  king  a  conditional  king.  The 
fourth  by  disabling  his  regiment,  and  making  him  appear  in- 
capable and  indign  to  reign."1  Coke's  view  that  mere  words 
coming  under  the  fourth  head  were  not  treason,  unless  accompanied 
by  some  other  overt  act,  prevailed.2  But  some  of  the  more 
general  rules  laid  down  by  Bacon  were,  as  we  shall  now  see, 
destined  to  prevail  in  the  succeeding  centuries ;  and  even  un- 
published writings  and  mere  words  were,  at  the  latter  part  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  allowed  to  have  a  weight  which  it  is  difficult 
to  suppose  would  have  been  approved  by  Coke  and  his  fellow 
judges. 

Thus,  by  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  con- 
structive extension  of  this  clause  of  the  statute  had  begun. 
During  the  latter  part  of  that  century  it  made  rapid  progress. 
Firstly,  it  was  laid  down  in  1663  that  a  conspiracy  to  levy  war 
could  be  regarded  as  an  overt  act  to  prove  a  compassing  of  the 
king's  death.3  Hale  approved  of  this  resolution ; 4  and  he  pointed 
out  that  some  of  the  sixteenth-century  cases  were  not  wholly  con- 
sistent with  Coke's  opinion  to  the  contrary.5  He  endeavoured  to 
reconcile  Coke's  opinion  with  the  new  construction  of  this  clause, 
by  drawing  a  distinction  between  a  mere  constructive  levying  of 
war 6  and  an  actual  levying  of  war.  He  held  that  a  conspiracy  to 
levy  what  was  merely  a  constructive  war  was  not,  and  a  conspiracy 
to  levy  an  actual  war  was,  an  overt  act  to  prove  a  compassing  of 
the  king's  death.7  This  distinction  is  accepted  by  Foster,8  and  is 
undoubtedly  good  law  ;  but  it  is  doubtful  if  it  really  expresses 
Coke's  meaning.  The  much  more  probable  view  is  that  the  con- 
structive interpretation  of  this  clause  had  been  extended  between 
the  dates  of  Coke's  and  Hale's  works.  It  was  both  an  obvious 
and  an  inevitable  extension,  but  it  was  none  the  less  an  extension. 
Secondly,  it  was  laid  down  in  R.  v.  Twyn 9  that  the  printing  of  a 
book,  in  which  the  people  were  incited  to  sedition,  to  rebellion, 

1  Spedding,  Letters  and  Life  of  Bacon  v  109.  2  Above  312. 

3  "  It  was  resolved  and  agreed  by  all  now  as  it  was  before  in  Tong's  case,  and 
Sir  H.  Vane's  case,  that  the  meeting  and  consulting  to  levy  war  is  an  overt  act  to  prove 
the  compassing  the  king's  death  within  the  stat.  of  25  Ed.  3.  Altho'  the  consulting 
to  levy  war  is  not  actual  levying  within  the  statute,  and  so  cannot  be  indicted  there- 
upon, for  that  treason  of  levying  war,  yet  if  they  be  indicted  for  the  treason  of 
compassing  and  imagining  the  king's  death,  that  consulting  to  levy  war  is  an  overt 
act  to  prove  that  treason,  altho'  Co.  PI.  Cor.  14  delivers  an  opinion  against  this," 
Kelyng  20. 

4  P.C.  i  119. 

5  Ibid  i  120-122 ;  it  is  clear,  for  instance,  that  the  line  between  a  conspiracy  with 
a  foreign  prince  to  invade  this  country,  which  Coke  admitted  to  be  a  good  overt  act 
to  prove  a  compassing  of  the  king's  death,  and  a  conspiracy  to  levy  war,  is  very  thin, 
see  ibid  122. 

6  For  what  amounts  to  a  constructive  levying  of  war  see  below  319-321. 

7  P.C.  i  122-123.  8  Crown  Law  213.  9  (1663)  Kelyng  22. 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  315 

and  to  the  killing  of  the  king,  was  an  overt  act,  which  could  be 
used  to  prove  a  compassing  of  his  death.  This  was  in  conformity 
with  Coke's  opinion.1  But  in  Algernon  Sidney  s  Case-  this  ruling 
was  extended  to  cover  the  case  of  a  writing,  in  which  it  was  in 
effect  alleged  that  the  king  was  subject  to  Parliament,  and  that 
kings  could  be  deposed.3  As  it  was  not  proved  that  the  paper 
was  published,4  this  goes  very  near  to  holding,  contrary  to  Coke's 
view,  and  in  accordance  with  actual  verdict  in  Peachairis  Case, 
that  the  mere  writing  of  such  a  paper  was  an  overt  act  of  com- 
passing the  king's  death.5  This  ruling  could  only  be  justified  in 
one  of  two  ways — either  on  the  unproved  assumption  that  the 
writing  was  intended  to  be  published,  or,  on  the  stronger  ground, 
that  it  was  so  connected  with  the  other  overt  acts  alleged,  that  the 
writing,  though  not  published,  was  evidence  to  support  and  ex- 
plain them.6  The  latter  ground  was,  as  we  shall  see,  accepted  as 
good  law  after  the  Revolution.7  Thirdly,  shortly  after  Pine's  Case,8 
in  which,  as  we  have  seen,  it  had  been  laid  down  that  merely 
scandalous  words  spoken  of  the  king  did  not  amount  to  treason,9 
it  had  been  laid  down  in  R.  v.  Crohagan 10  that,  if  words  purporting 
an  intention  to  kill  the  king  were  accompanied  by  an  overt  act, 
which  seemed  to  imply  an  intention  to  put  the  intention  into  exe- 
cution, this  would  amount  to  treason.  In  that  case  the  accused, 
being  at  Lisbon,  had  said,  M  I  will  kill  the  king  if  I  may  come  to 
him."  He  had  then  come  to  England,  and,  when  arrested,  had 
spoken  scornfully  of  the  king.  It  was  held  that  he  was  rightly 
convicted  for  compassing  the  king's  death.  This  case  came  near 
to  that  of  R.  v.  Owen  ;  u  but  the  court  seems  to  have  laid  some  stress 

I  Above  312  and  n.  3.  *  (1683)  9  S.T.  818. 

3  See  the  indictment  ibid  at  p.  819;  and  the  passages  from  the  book  read  to  the 
court,  ibid  at  pp.  855-858. 

4  Sidney  denied  that  he  had  ever  published  anything  in  his  life,  ibid  878 ;  and 
no  evidence  was  offered  that  he  intended  to  publish  these  papers. 

5  Thus  Jeffreys,  C.J.,  said  in  his  summing  up,  "in  the  next  place  I  am  to  tell  you, 
that  though  some  judges  have  been  of  opinion  that  words  of  themselves  are  not  an 
overt  act ;  but  my  lord  Hales  nor  my  lord  Coke,  nor  any  other  of  the  sages  of  the  law, 
ever  questioned  but  that  a  letter  would  be  an  overt  act  sufficient  to  prove  a  man  guilty 
of  high  treason ;  for  scribere  est  agere"  ibid  at  p.  889. 

6  "  Another  thing  which  I  must  take  notice  of  to  you  in  this  case,  is  to  mind  you, 
how  this  book  contains  all  the  malice  and  revenge  and  treason  that  mankind  can  be 
guilty  of:  it  fixes  the  sole  power  in  the  parliament  and  the  people ;  so  that  he  carries 
on  the  design  still,  for  their  debates  at  their  meetings  were  to  that  purpose.  And 
such  doctrines  as  these  suit  with  their  debates  ;  for  there  a  general  insurrection  was 
designed,  and  that  was  discoursed  of  in  this  book  and  encouraged,"  ibid  at 
p.  893;  Foster  admits,  Crown  Law,  198,  that  if,  "the  papers  found  in  Mr.  Sidney's 
closet  had  been  plainly  relative  to  the  other  treasonable  practices  charged  in  the  in- 
dictment, they  might  have  been  read  in  evidence  against  him,  though  not  published." 

7  Below  316-317.  8  (1629)  Cro.  Car.  117. 
9  Above  312.                                         10  (1634)  Cro.  Car.  332. 

II  (1616)  1  Rolle  Rep.  185  ;  above  ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  115-116,  draws  from  these  cases 
the  moral  that  words,  "  that  are  expressly  menacing  the  death  or  destruction  of  the 
king,  are  a  sufficient  overt  act  to  prove  that  compassing  of  his  death  "  ;  in  Crohagan's 
Case  he  lays  stress  on  the  act  of  coming  to  England. 


316  CRIME  AND  TORT 

upon  the  facts  that  the  words  were  accompanied  by  the  overt  act 
of  coming  to  England,  and  that  he  had  used  scornful  words  when 
arrested ;  and  this  is  the  manner  in  which  the  case  was  explained 
and  justified  by  later  lawyers.1  It  followed  that  words  could  give 
a  treasonable  colour  to  an  otherwise  innocent  overt  act.  It  is, 
therefore,  not  surprising  that,  in  1660,  the  judges  showed  a 
tendency  to  minimize  the  importance  of  the  difference  between 
written  and  spoken  words.  "Words  spoken,"  it  was  said,2  "are 
the  same  thing  if  they  be  proved.  Words  are  the  natural  way  for 
a  man  whereby  to  express  the  imaginations  of  the  heart.  If  it  be 
any  way  declared  that  a  man  imagineth  the  king's  death,  that  is 
treason  within  the  stat.  25  Edw.  3."  And  this  tendency  appears 
in  Jeffreys'  summing  up  in  Sidney  s  Case.3 

The  view  that  there  was  no  difference  between  written  and 
spoken  words  was  not  followed  after  the  Revolution.  The  rule 
adopted  was  in  accordance  with  the  cases  decided  earlier  in  this 
century — R.  v.  Owen,  Pines  Case,  and  R.  v.  Crohagan.  "Loose 
words,"  said  Holt,  C.J.,  in  1696,4  "spoken  without  relation  to  any 
act  or  project  are  not  treason  :  but  words  of  persuasion  to  kill  the 
king  are  overt  acts  of  high  treason ;  so  is  a  consulting  how  to  kill 
the  king ;  so  if  two  men  agree  together  to  kill  the  king,  for  the 
bare  imagination  and  compassing  makes  the  treason,  and  any  ex- 
ternal act  that  is  a  sufficient  manifestation  of  that  compassing  and 
imagining  is  an  overt  act " ;  and  words,  as  Foster  says,5  "  may 
explain  the  meaning  of  an  overt  act."  But  it  was  only  under 
these  conditions  that  words  could  be  an  overt  act  of  treason. 
Similarly,  the  view  that  unpublished  writings  could  be  given  in 
evidence  to  prove  an  overt  act  of  compassing,  was  rejected.  Such 
writings  can  only  be  given  in  evidence  if  they  are  relevant  to  en- 
force or  explain  other  overt  acts  charged  in  the  indictment.  Thus, 
as  Foster  explains,6  "the  papers  found  in  Lord  Preston's  custody, 
those  found  where  Mr.  Layer  had  lodged  them,  the  intercepted 
letters  of  Dr.  Hensey,  were  all  read  in  evidence  as  overt  acts  of 
the  treason  respectively  charged  on  them.   .  .  .   For  those  letters 

1  Foster,  Crown  Law  203.  2  Kelyng  13.  3  Above  315  n.  6. 

4Charnock's  Case  2  Salk.  631:  "the  difference  (between  words  and  writings) 
appeareth  to  me  to  be  very  great,  and  it  lieth  here.  Seditious  writings  are  per- 
manent things,  and  if  published  they  scatter  the  poison  far  and  wide.  They  are 
acts  of  deliberation,  capable  of  satisfactory  proof,  and  not  ordinarily  liable  to  mis- 
construction. .  .  .  Words  are  transient  and  fleeting  as  the  wind,  the  poison  they 
scatter  is  at  the  worst  confined  to  the  narrow  circle  of  a  few  hearers.  They  are 
frequently  the  effect  of  a  sudden  transport,  easily  misunderstood  and  often  misre- 
ported,"  Foster,  Crown  Law  204. 

6  Crown  Law  204  ;  he  says  that  the  reasons  which  Hale  gives  for  this  rule  (P.C.  i 
m-115,  323)  "founded  on  temporary  Acts  or  Acts  since  repealed,  which  make 
speaking  the  words  therein  set  forth  felony  or  misdemeanour,  are  unanswerable," 
ibid  201. 

6  Ibid  198. 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  317 

and  papers  were  written  in  prosecution  of  certain  determinate 
purposes  which  were  all  treasonable  and  then  in  contemplation  of 
the  offenders,  and  were  plainly  connected  with  them."  The  rule 
as  so  settled  was  probably  the  rule  which  Hale  considered  to  be 
the  law.1 

But,  except  in  these  two  cases,  the  seventeenth-century 
decisions,  extending  the  constructive  interpretation  of  this  clause, 
were  adopted,  and  even  carried  further,  after  the  Revolution. 
And,  here  again,  the  extension  was  probably  inevitable.  If  a  con- 
spiracy to  levy  war,  and  the  publication  of  a  writing  advocating  the 
deposition  of  the  king,  or  merely  arguing  that  it  is  lawful  to  depose 
him,  are  overt  acts  which  can  be  given  in  evidence  to  prove  the 
compassing  of  his  death,  it  will  be  difficult  to  draw  the  line  at  these 
acts.  It  will  be  difficult  to  rule  out  any  acts  done  in  preparation 
for  any  other  act,  which,  if  accomplished,  will  be  an  overt  act. 
That  no  attempt  was  made  to  draw  the  line  is  clear  from  the  case 
of  Lord  Preston.2 

Foster's  summary  of  that  case  is  as  follows:3  "Lord  Preston 
and  two  other  gentlemen  had  procured  a  smack  to  transport  them 
to  France,  but  were  stopped  before  they  got  out  of  the  river,  and 
their  papers  seized  Among  the  papers  was  found  a  scheme  in- 
tended to  be  laid  before  the  French  king  or  his  ministers  for 
invading  the  kingdom  in  favour  of  the  late  king  James  II.  ;  with 
many  letters,  notes  and  memoranda,  all  tending  to  the  same  pur- 
pose. Lord  Preston  upon  his  trial  insisted,  among  other  matters, 
that  no  overt  act  was  proved  upon  him  in  Middlesex,  where  all 
the  overt  acts  were  laid,  for  he  was  taken  with  the  papers  in  the 
county  of  Kent  But  the  court  told  the  jury,  that  if  upon  the 
whole  evidence  they  did  believe  that  his  lordship  had  an  intention 
of  going  into  France,  and  to  carry  those  papers  thither  for  the 
purposes  charged  in  the  indictment,  his  taking  boat  at  Surrey  stairs 
which  are  in  Middlesex,  in  order  to  go  on  board  the  smack,  was  a 
sufficient  overt  act  in  Middlesex.  Every  step  taken  for  those 
purposes  was  an  overt  act."  4  The  last  sentence  contains  the  gist 
of  the  matter.  It  comes  to  this — every  act,  however  remotely 
connected  with  an  overt  act  of  compassing  the  king's  death,  is  itself 
an  overt  act     As  the  future  Lord   Eldon  contended,  when,  as 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  118  ;  Foster,  Crown  Law  198. 

2  (1691)  12  S.T.  646.  3  Crown  Law  196. 

*  "  Gentlemen  give  me  leave  to  tell  you,  if  you  are  satisfied  upon  this  evidence 
that  my  lord  was  privy  to  this  design,  contained  in  these  papers,  and  was  going  with 
them  into  France,  there  to  excite  an  invasion  of  the  kingdom,  to  depose  the  king  and 
queen,  and  made  use  of  the  papers  to  that  end,  then  every  step  he  took  in  order  to 
it,  is  high  treason  wherever  he  went ;  his  taking  water  at  Surrey  stairs  in  the  county 
of  Middlesex  will  be  as  much  high  treason  as  the  going  a  ship-board  in  Surrey,  or 
being  found  on  ship-board  in  Kent,  where  the  papers  were  taken,"  per  Holt,  C.J., 
12  S.T.  at  p.  740. 


318  CRIME  AND  TORT 

attorney-general,  he  was  prosecuting  Hardy  in  1794/  any  act 
which  showed  that  the  person  doing  it  intended  "  to  put  the  king 
in  circumstances  in  which,  according  to  the  ordinary  experience  of 
mankind,  his  life  would  be  in  danger,"  might  be  given  in  evidence 
as  an  overt  act  of  compassing  his  death.  It  followed  that  this 
clause  of  the  statute  could  be  made  to  cover  the  ground  covered 
both  by  the  clause  against  levying  war  against  the  king,  and  by 
the  clause  against  adhering  to  his  enemies.2 

It  was  attempted  in  1794  to  apply  these  doctrines  to  the 
activities  of  the  Constitutional  and  the  London  Corresponding 
Societies.3  They  were  advocating  universal  suffrage  and  annual 
Parliaments ;  and  they  carried  on  their  propaganda  through  their 
branches,  and  through  a  convention  in  which  their  branches  were 
represented.  They  asserted  that  they  only  wished  to  press  for 
these  reforms  by  constitutional  means.  The  Crown  asserted  that 
they  were  preparing  for  the  deposition  of  the  king  and  the  estab- 
lishment of  a  republic.  The  jury,  by  acquitting  them,  showed  that 
they  did  not  believe  the  contentions  of  the  crown.  But  this  ac- 
quittal by  no  means  meant  the  end  of  the  doctrine  of  constructive 
treason.  As  Stephen  has  pointed  out,  it  was  applied  in  1797  and 
1798.4  But  the  trials  of  1794  showed  that  it  was  an  exceedingly 
unpopular  doctrine ;  and  the  acquittals  may  have  been  partly 
due  to  that  fact.5  However  that  may  be,  it  was  in  1795  6  that  we 
got  the  first  of  those  statutory  interferences  with  the  doctrine, 
which  have  ended  by  putting  the  law  on  a  different  basis.  But 
with  this  legislation  I  cannot  deal  till  I  have  considered  the  con- 
structive extension  of  the  clause  as  to  levying  war  against  the 
king. 

(2)  Levying  war  against  the  king. 

The  offence  declared  to  be  treason  by  Edward  III.'s  statute 
was  the  actual  levying  of  war,  and  not  a  conspiracy  to  levy  war. 
A  conspiracy  to  levy  war  was  not  made  treason  by  the  statute ; 
and  this  defect  was,  as  we  have  seen,  cured  at  first  by  statute,7 
and  eventually  by  the  constructive  extension  of  the  clause  directed 
against  the  compassing  or  imagining  the  king's  death.8  Thus, 
the  wording  of  the  clause  against  levying  war,  shows  that  its 
constructive  extension  was  bound  to  follow  a  line  very  different 
from  that  followed  in  the  case  of  the  clause  which  has  just  been 

1  24  S.T.  at  p.  256,  cited  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  276. 

2  Foster,  Crown  Law  197 — "  levying  war  is  an  overt  act  of  compassing  .  .  .  and 
so  is  a  treasonable  correspondence  with  the  enemy,  though  it  falleth  more  naturally 
within  the  clause  of  adhering  to  the  king's  enemies." 

3 24  S.T.  199  (Trial  of  Hardy);  25  S.T.  1  (Trial  of  Home  Tooke) ;  Stephen, 
H.C.L.  ii  274-277. 

4  H.C.L.  ii  278-279.  8  Ibid  277.                      6  36  George  III.  c.  7. 

7  Vol.  iv  496-497.  8  Above  311  seqq. 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  319 

considered.  In  fact  it  proceeded  upon  the  line  of  giving  a  greatly 
extended  meaning  to  the  phrase  "  levying  war." 

It  is  probable  that  the  extensive  construction  put  upon  this 
clause  began  at  an  earlier  date  than  that  put  upon  the  clause  as  to 
the  compassing  of  the  king's  death ;  and  that  it  was  suggested 
by  the  distinction,  drawn  in  the  statute  itself,  between  levying  war 
against  the  king,  and  a  mere  private  war.1  Coke  tells  us  that  "  it 
was  resolved  by  all  the  judges  of  England  in  the  reign  of  king  H. 
8  that  an  insurrection  against  the  statute  of  Labourers,  for  the  in- 
hansing  of  salaries  and  wages,  was  a  levying  of  war  against  the 
king,  because  it  was  generally  against  the  king's  law,  and  the 
offenders  took  upon  them  the  reformation  thereof,  which  subjects 
by  gathering  of  power  ought  not  to  do."2  This,  Hale  tells  us, 
is  the  first  instance  that  he  had  seen  of  "this  interpretative  levy- 
ing of  war."  3  But  it  is  clear  that  the  judges,  who  came  to  this 
resolution,  had  arrived  at  the  principle  upon  which  the  constructive 
extension  of  this  clause  proceeded — the  distinction  between  the 
use  of  force  for  a  merely  private  end  which  was  a  mere  riot,  and 
the  use  of  force  for  a  public  object  which  was  treason ;  and  it  is 
clear  that  this  distinction  is  directly  suggested  by  the  statute.4 

This  distinction  was  applied  in  many  cases  in  the  sixteenth 
and  seventeenth  centuries.  Thus  in  1 597,  in  the  case  of  R.  v  Brad- 
shaw  and  Others,  it  was  resolved  that  a  rising  to  put  down  all  en- 
closures was  a  levying  of  war  within  the  statute ; 5  and  no  doubt 
the  judges  were  encouraged  to  give  this  wide  construction  to  the 
statute  by  the  Legislature,  which  had  shown  a  readiness  to 
extend  it  by  making  a  conspiracy  to  levy  war,  and  occasionally 
even  a  mere  riot,  treason.6  But  it  is  obvious  that  it  was  some- 
times difficult  to  draw  the  line  between  a  riot  raised  to  gratify  a 
merely  private  quarrel,  and  a  riot  raised  to  effect  some  public 
general  object  Thus,  in  the  case  of  a  riot  of  weavers  in  1675, 
for  the  purpose  of  destroying  engine  looms,  the  judges  were 
equally  divided  as  to  whether  it  was  treason  or  not  Those  who 
held  that  it  was  treason  emphasized  the  fact  that  the  design  was 
to  destroy  all  engine  looms.  Those  who  held  that  it  was  not, 
regarded  it  as  being  "only  a  particular  quarrel  and  grievance  be- 
tween men  of  the  same  trade  against  a  particular  engine  that  they 
thought  a  grievance  to  them."7  And  the  manner  in  which  the 
provisions  of  the  statutes  already  referred  to,  had  extended  this 
clause,  sometimes  caused  a  difference  of  opinion.     Thus,  in  1668, 

1  Vol.  iii  291 ;  Coke  cites  these  words  of  the  statute,  and  then  says,  "  whereby  it 
appeareth  that  bearing  of  arms  in  war-like  manner,  for  a  private  revenge  or  end,  is  no 
levying  of  war  against  the  king  within  this  statute.  So  that  every  gathering  of  force  is 
not  high  treason,"  Third  Instit.  10. 

2  Third  Instit  10.  •  P.C.  i  132.  *  Above  n.  1. 

8  Third  Instit,  9,  10.  «Vol.  iv  497.  '  Hale,  P.C.  i  i43*-i46\ 


320  CRIME  AND  TORT 

in  the  case  of  R.  v  Messenger,  Basely  and  Others,  Hale  refused 
to  agree  with  the  other  judges  that  a  riot  to  pull  down  bawdy 
houses,  and  to  release  prisoners,  was  treason,  on  the  ground  that  a 
statute  of  Mary  had  enacted  that  such  offences  were  felony.1  It 
was,  however,  agreed  on  all  hands  that  there  must  be  clear  evi- 
dence that  the  intention  was  to  effect  a  purpose  by  warlike 
violence ; 2  and  that,  if  several  persons  had  agreed  to  levy  war, 
and  some  had  proceeded  with  their  warlike  design,  and  others 
had  not  actually  appeared  in  arms,  the  latter  were  equally  guilty 
of  treason,  because  there  are  no  accessories  in  treason.3 

As  in  the  case  of  the  constructive  extension  of  the  clause  dir- 
ected against  the  compassing  or  imagining  the  king's  death,  so 
in  the  case  of  this  clause,  the  Revolution  did  not  stop  the  develop- 
ment of  the  law.  The  law  laid  down  by  Coke  and  Hale  was  re- 
stated and  applied  in  1 710  in  the  case  of  Dammaree  and  Purchase ,4 
who  were  convicted  of  treason  for  raising  a  riot  to  destroy  all  dis- 
senting meeting-houses.  In  Stephen's  opinion,  their  conviction 
was  a  more  severe  application  of  the  law  than  any  of  the  previous 
decisions5 — indeed  he  almost  questions  its  correctness.6  But  it 
is  difficult  to  see  what  other  conclusion  could  have  been  reached, 
without  disregarding  established  authority ;  and  Foster  does  not 
question  its  correctness.7  The  provisions  of  the  Riot  Act  of 
17148  have  generally  prevented  a  recourse  to  the  doctrine 
applied  in  that  case.  But  it  was  always  possible  to  have  recourse 
to  it;  and  in  1781  Lord  George  Gordon  was  indicted  for  treason 
for  helping  to  excite  the  riots,  which  raged  between  June  2nd  and 
June  6th  in  that  year,  in  consequence  of  the  passing  of  the  Act 
which  had  mitigated  the  penalties  to  which  Roman  Catholics  were 
liable.9  In  his  charge  to  the  jury  Lord  Mansfield  laid  down  the 
law  exactly  as  it  had  been  laid  down  by  Coke,  Hale,  and  Foster.10 
Lord  George  Gordon  was  acquitted,  partly  because  the  jury  took 

1  Kelyng  75  ;  P.C.  i  134-135.  2  Hale,  P.C.  i  150  ;  below  328. 

3  Kelyng  19.  *  15  S.T.  522.  5  H.C.L.  ii  270. 

6  "  If  Dammaree's  case  is  good  law  it  seems  difficult  to  say  that  any  riot  excited 
by  any  unpopular  measure,  whether  executive  or  legislative,  is  not  high  treason,"  ibid 
ii  271. 

7  See  his  account  of  the  case  which  he  had  heard  when  a  student,  Crown  Law 
213-216. 

8  1  George  I.  st.  2  c.  5 ;  below  328-329.  9  21  S.T.  485. 

10  "  There  are  two  kinds  of  levying  war  : — one  against  the  person  of  the  king  ;  to 
imprison,  to  dethrone,  or  to  kill  him  ;  or  to  make  him  change  measures  or  remove 
counsellors — the  other  which  is  said  to  be  levied  against  the  majesty  of  the  king,  or,  in 
other  words  against  him  in  his  regal  capacity ;  as  when  a  multitude  rise  and  assemble 
to  attain  by  force  and  violence  any  object  of  a  general  public  nature ;  that  is  levying 
war  against  the  majesty  of  the  king ;  and  most  reasonably  so  held  because  it  tends  to 
dissolve  all  the  bonds  of  society,  to  destroy  property,  and  to  overturn  government ; 
and  by  force  of  arms  to  restrain  the  king  from  reigning  according  to  law.  Insurrections 
by  force  and  violence  to  raise  the  price  of  wages,  to  open  all  prisons,  to  destroy 
meeting-houses,  nay  to  destroy  all  brothels,  to  resist  the  execution  of  militia  laws,  to 
throw  down  all  inclosures  ....  have  all  been  held  levying  war,"  ibid  at  p.  644. 


CONSTRUCTIVE  TREASON  321 

the  view,  strongly  urged  upon  them  by  Erskine,1  his  counsel, 
that  he  had  had  nothing  to  do  with  the  riots ;  and  partly  perhaps 
because  they  disliked  the  doctrine  of  constructive  treason.2  This 
case,  therefore,  like  the  cases  of  Hardy  and  Home  Tooke,3  effected 
no  modification  in  the  legal  doctrine  of  constructive  treason  ;  but, 
like  those  cases,  it  showed  that  some  change  in  the  law  was 
needed.  But,  though,  as  we  shall  now  see,  important  changes 
have  been  made,  these  changes  have  not  affected  this  part  of  the 
doctrine  of  constructive  treason. 

(3)   The  later  history. 

In  1795  4  a  statute  was  passed  which,  in  effect,  gave  statutory 
force  to  the  constructions  which  had  been  put  upon  the  clause  of 
Edward  III.'s  statute  relating  to  the  compassing  of  the  king's 
death.  It  provided  that  it  should  be  treason  to  compass  :  (i)  not 
only  the  death,  but  also  the  bodily  harm,  imprisonment,  or  restraint 
of  the  person  of  the  king,  or  his  deposition ;  (ii)  the  levying  of 
war  on  him  either  in  order  to  compel  him  to  change  his  policy,  or 
in  order  to  overawe  both  or  either  of  the  houses  of  Parliament ; 
(iii)  the  stirring  up  of  any  foreigner  to  invade  any  part  of  the  king's 
dominions ;  such  compassing  being  evidenced  by  printing,  writing 
or  other  overt  act.  In  1 848  5  it  was  in  effect  enacted  that,  such 
of  the  treasons  set  out  in  the  last  cited  Act  as  related  to  the  com- 
passing the  death  or  bodily  harm,  the  imprisonment  or  restraint  of 
the  person  of  the  king,  should  be  treason  ;  and  that  the  other 
compassings  specified  in  the  Act  should  be  felony.6  But  nothing 
in  the  Act  was  to  affect  the  statute  of  Edward  III.7  That  statute 
must  of  course  be  taken  to  bear  the  construction  which  the  judges 
have  put  upon  it ;  for  there  is  nothing  in  this  legislation  to  negative 
that  construction.8  The  result  is  that  the  acts  made  felony  by  the 
statute  of  1848  could,  if  the  crown  wished,  be  treated  as  construc- 
tive treason  by  virtue  of  the  Act  of  Edward  III.  As  Professor 
Kenny   justly   says,9   it    is   "a   singular  juridical    anomaly    that 

1 21  S.T.  587-621 ;  see  especially  pp.  591-592,  cited  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  273,  and  the 
peroration  at  pp.  616-621. 

2  Dr.  Johnson's  saying  (cited  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  272  n.)  that  "  he  was  glad  Lord 
George  Gordon  had  escaped  rather  than  a  precedent  should  be  established  of  hanging 
a  man  for  constructive  treason,"  is  well  known. 

3  Above  318. 

4  36  George  III.  c.  7  §  1 ;  made  perpetual  by  57  George  III.  c.  6  §  1. 

5  n,  12  Victoria  c.  12  §  1 ;  the  object  of  the  Act  was,  by  diminishing  the  penalty, 
to  render  it  easier  "to  prosecute  these  crimes  with  success,"  Kenny,  Criminal  Law 
274. 

6§3- 

7  "  Provided  always  .  .  .  that  nothing  herein  contained  shall  lessen  the  force  of 
or  in  any  manner  affect  anything  enacted  by  the  statute  passed  in  the  twenty-fifth 
year  of  king  Edward  III.,"  §  6. 

8  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  280.  9  Criminal  Law  274. 
VOL.  VIII. — 21 


322  CRIME  AND  TORT 

precisely  the   same  action    should    thus   occupy,    simultaneously, 
two  different  grades  in  the  sphere  of  crime." 

This  legislation  did  not  touch  the  clause  relating  to  the  levying 
of  war  against  the  king.  The  result  is  that  the  constructive  ex- 
tension of  this  clause  is  in  no  way  affected.  Therefore,  as  Stephen 
says,1  "  a  great  riot  for  any  public  object "  could  still  be  treated  as 
treason. 

Offences  Cognate  to   Treason 

At  the  time  when  the  statute  of  Edward  III.  was  passed  treason 
was  regarded  rather  as  an  offence  against  the  person  of  the  king 
than  as  an  offence  against  the  state.2  It  has  never  ceased  to  be 
an  offence  against  the  person  of  the  king.  In  fact,  since  the  Act 
of  1848,  it  is  only  offences  against  the  state  which  take  the  form  of 
attempts  against  the  person  of  the  king,  which  must  be  treated  as 
treason.  But  it  is  obvious  that,  as  the  conception  of  the  state  was 
more  distinctly  realized,  and  as  the  king  came  to  be  conceived  as 
the  head  and  representative  of  the  state,  treason  must  come  to  be 
regarded  as  essentially  an  offence,  and  the  most  heinous  offence, 
against  the  state.  We  have  seen  that  technical  expression  was 
given  to  this  transformation  in  the  conception  of  treason,  partly  by 
the  Legislature,  and  partly  by  the  growth  of  the  doctrine  of  con- 
structive treason.  And,  as  the  result  of  this  transformation,  we 
can  see  the  growth  of  a  group  of  offences  cognate  to  treason.  As 
compared  with  treason  they  are  minor  offences  ;  but  they  all  have 
this  feature  in  common  with  treason  that  they  are  either  (i)  seditious 
in  character  or  tendency,  i.e.  they  aim  directly  at  the  diminution  of 
the  authority  of  the  state ;  or  (ii)  if  not  seditious,  they  involve 
serious  breaches  of  the  peace,  and  an  interference  with  the  orderly 
government  of  the  state.  I  have  already  dealt  with  such  of  these 
cognate  offences  as  were  created  by  statute  during  the  sixteenth 
and  seventeenth  centuries.3  At  this  point  I  propose  to  deal  with 
such  of  these  offences  as  were  mainly  shaped  by  the  writings  of 
the  lawyers  and  the  decisions  of  the  courts. 

The  offences,  directly  seditious,  which  fall  under  the  first  of 
these  heads,  are,  firstly,  the  publication  of  seditious  words  or  writ- 
ings, and,  secondly,  seditious  conspiracies.  Of  these  two  matters 
I  shall  speak  in  the  two  following  sections.4  The  offences,  less 
directly  seditious,  which  fall  under  the  second  of  these  heads,  are 
misprision  of  treason,  and  unlawful  assemblies  routs  and  riots.  It 
is  with  these  topics  that  I  shall  now  deal. 

(1)  Misprision  of  treason. 

We  have  seen  that  the  term  "  misprision  "  meant  originally  the 
offence  committed  by  a  person  who,  knowing  that  a  treason  or 

1  H.C.L.  ii  280-281.  2  Vol.  iii  289-290. 

3  Vol.  iv  497.  503  ;  vol.  vi   399-400.  ■*  Below  337-346,  379-384- 


OFFENCES  COGNATE  TO  TREASON  323 

felony  had  been  committed,  failed  to  disclose  it ; !  but  that  in  the 
sixteenth  century  it  had  got  an  extended  meaning.2  When  we 
talk  of  misprision  of  treason  or  felony  we  are  using  the  term  in  its 
original  sense  ;  and  that  its  original  sense  was  distinct  from  its 
secondary  sense  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  Coke  deals  with  mis- 
prision of  treason  and  felony,  and  with  misprision  generally,  in 
separate  chapters.3 

When  Coke  wrote,  the  offence  had,  as  a  result  of  statutes  of 
Edward  VI.  and  Mary's  reigns,  been  distinguished  from  treason ; 
and,  even  before  that  time,  its  punishment  had  been  definitely 
fixed.4  Its  punishment  was  imprisonment  for  life,  forfeiture  of 
goods,  and  forfeiture  of  the  profits  of  land  for  life.5  Misprision  of 
felony  bore  the  same  relation  to  felony  as  misprision  of  treason 
bore  to  treason.  It  differed  only  in  the  fact  that  its  punishment — 
fine  and  imprisonment 6 — was  less  severe.  But,  though  by  the 
middle  of  the  sixteenth  century  misprision  of  treason  had  been 
distinguished  from  treason,  it  was  not  till  the  middle  of  the  seven- 
teenth century  that  the  two  offences  were  clearly  differentiated,  by 
the  definition  of  the  extent  of  the  knowledge,  the  concealment  of 
which  would  amount  to  misprision.  Firstly,  in  1662  it  was  re- 
solved by  the  judges,"  "  that  where  a  person  knowing  of  the  design 
does  meet  with  them,  and  hear  them  discourse  of  their  traitorous 
designs,  and  say  or  act  nothing ;  this  is  high  treason  in  that  party, 
for  it  is  more  than  a  bare  concealment,  which  is  misprision,  because 
it  sheweth  his  liking  and  approving  of  their  design  ;  but  if  a  person 
not  knowing  of  their  design  before,  come  into  their  company,  and 
hear  their  discourses,  and  say  nothing,  and  never  meet  with  them 
again  at  their  consultations,  that  concealment  is  only  misprision  of 
high  treason.  But  if  he  meet  with  them  again,  and  hear  their 
consultations,  and  then  conceal  it,  this  is  high  treason.  For  it 
sheweth  a  liking  and  an  approving  of  their  design."  Secondly, 
in  1663  it  was  resolved8  that  "to  make  a  misprision  of  treason, 
there  must  be  a  knowledge  of  the  design,  and  of  the  persons 
or  some  of  them ;  for  a  man  cannot  be  said  to  conceal  what  he 
doth  not  know  ;  and  therefore  if  one  tell  J.  S.  in  general,  that 
there  will  be  a  rising  without  acquainting  him  with  the  persons 

1  Vol  iii  3S8-389.  2  Ibid  389  n.  1.  3  Third  Instit.  cap.  iii  and  lxv. 

4  '•  Tho'  some  question  was  antiently,  whether  bare  concealment  of  high  treason 
were  treason  (vol.  iii  3S9  n.  i),  yet  that  is  settled  by  the  statute  of  5,  6  E.  6  cap.  11, 
and  1,  2  P.  and  M.  cap.  10,  viz.  that  concealment  or  keeping  secret  of  high  treason 
shall  be  deemed  and  taken  only  misprision  of  treason,  and  the  offender  therein  to 
suffer  and  forfeit,  as  in  cases  of  misprision  of  treason,  as  hath  heretofore  been  used," 
Hale,  P.C.  i  371. 

5  Coke,  Third.  Instit.  36  ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  374.  «  Coke,  Third  Instit.  36. 
7R.  v.  Tong,  Kelyng  17;   there  was  a  similar  resolution  in  the  following  year 

ibid  21. 

8  Kelyng  21,  22. 


324  CRIME  AND  TORT 

who  are  to  rise  or  with  the  nature  of  the  plot,  if  J.  S.  conceal 
this,  this  is  no  misprision  of  treason,  because  he  hath  no  knowledge 
of  the  treason." 

Certain  statutes  of  Elizabeth's  reign  made  misprision  of  treason 
"a  kind  of  substantive  offence,  and  not  consequential  upon  the 
making  of  treason." *  For  instance  those  who  counterfeited  foreign 
gold  coin,2  or  who  failed  to  disclose  any  offer  of  reconciliation  to 
the  Roman  Catholic  religion,3  or  who  aided  or  maintained  any 
person  who  tried  to  pervert  any  of  the  queen's  subjects  from  their 
allegiance  to  the  church  as  by  law  established,4  were  declared  to 
be  guilty  of  this  offence. 

(2)   Unlawful  assemblies  routs  and  riots. 

It  would  seem  that  these  three  allied  offences  were  beginning 
to  acquire  their  modern  characteristics  during  the  latter  part  of  the 
sixteenth  century.  A  note  in  Brooke's  Abridgment  states  in 
substance  that  the  offence  of  unlawful  assembly  is  committed,  if 
there  is  an  assembly  for  an  illegal  purpose  against  the  peace,  though 
nothing  is  done  in  pursuance  of  that  purpose  ;  that  if  the  assembly 
proceed  on  their  way  to  the  execution  of  their  purpose  the  unlaw- 
ful assembly  becomes  a  rout ;  that  if  they  proceed  to  execute  their 
illegal  purpose  the  rout  becomes  a  riot ;  and  that  the  offence  of 
riot,  and  therefore  of  rout  and  unlawful  assembly,  cannot  be  com- 
mitted by  less  than  three  persons.5  These  definitions  given  by 
Brooke,  and,  as  we  have  seen,6  the  treatment  of  these  offences  by 
the  court  of  Star  Chamber,  are  the  foundation  of  the  definitions  of 
these  offences  recognized  by  our  modern  law. 

Of  the  offence  of  "  rout"  it  is  not  necessary  to  speak  further. 
The  two  important  offences  are  unlawful  assembly  and  riot     We 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  376.  2  14  Elizabeth  c.  3.  3  13  Elizabeth  c.  2. 

4  23  Elizabeth  c.  1.     All  these  statutes  are  cited,  Hale,  P.C.  i  376-377. 

5".\ota  quod  intelligitur  quod  ryot  nest  nisi  per  3  al  meyns,  et  doyent  faire 
illoyal  acte,  mes  poet  estre  illoyal  assemble,  si  le  peuple  eux  assemble  insimul  pur 
male  purpose  contra  pacem,  coment  que  ils  fesont  rien,  tamen  videtur  per  rehearshals 
in  statutes  que  si  ils  eurent  assembles  et  puis  procedunt  ou  chivauchent,  ou  allent 
avant,  ou  mouvent  per  instigacion  dun  ou  plures  que  est  conductor  de  eux,  cest  un 
route,  eoque  ils  meuvent,  et  procede  en  route  et  nomber,"  Bro.  ab.  Riots  pi.  4 ;  Coke, 
on  the  other  hand,  adopted,  from  Marowe's  Reading,  Bro.  loc.  cit.  pi.  5,  Putman, 
Oxford  Studies  vol.  vii  339,  another  definition  of  a  rout — it  signifieth,  he  says,  "  when 
three  or  more  do  any  unlawful  act  for  their  own  or  the  common  quarrel  etc.  as  when 
commoners  break  down  hedges  or  pales,  or  cast  down  ditches,  or  inhabitants  for  a 
way  claimed  by  them  or  the  like,"  Third  Instit.  176;  but,  as  Brooke  says,  the  first 
definition  is  the  better,  and  it  is  that  which  is  now  recognized,  Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  i 
c.  65  §  8 ;  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  283  ;  Blackstone,  Comm.  iv  146,  tries  to  combine 
the  two. 

6  Vol.  v  ig8-igg;  [note  it  should  have  been  there  pointed  out  that  Hudson's 
definition  of  a  rout  is  more  correct  than  Coke's  and  Marowe's,  and  is  probably  based 
on  Brooke's;  at  p.  198  line  9  for  "both  by  Hudson  and  Coke  "  read  "by  Marowe, 
Brooke,  Hudson  and  Coke,"  and  line  one  from  the  bottom  for  "  Coke "  read 
"  Brooke."] 


OFFENCES  COGNATE  TO  TREASON  325 

have  seen  that  certain  kinds  of  acts,  which  are  included  in  the 
definition  of  these  two  offences,  had  been  the  subject  of  important 
statutes  of  Edward  VI.,  Mary  and  Elizabeth's  reigns  ; l  and,  during 
the  whole  of  this  period,  both  ofifences  were  becoming  the  centres 
of  important  bodies  of  legal  doctrine.  I  shall  deal  with  the  de- 
velopment of  this  body  of  legal  doctrine  under  the  following  heads  : 
(i)  The  definition  of  these  offences ;  (ii)  the  relation  between  the 
repeal  of  the  earlier  legislation  on  the  subject  of  riot  to  the  distinc- 
tion between  riot  and  treason  ;  and  (iii)  the  liabilities  of  rioters,  and 
the  measures  which  may  or  ought  to  be  taken  for  the  suppression  of 
riots,  and  the  dispersal  of  unlawful  assemblies. 

(i)  The  definition  of  these  offences. 

The  view  recognized  by  the  court  of  Star  Chamber,2  that  it 
takes  at  least  three  persons  to  commit  the  offence  of  riot  or  unlaw- 
ful assembly,  was  acted  upon  in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Sudbury  in  1700.3 
In  that  case  three  persons  having  been  indicted  for  an  unlawful 
assembly  a  rout  and  a  riot,  one  was  acquitted  and  two  found  guilty ; 
and  judgment  was  arrested  because  two  could  not  be  guilty  of  these 
offences.4  It  is  obvious  that  to  constitute  a  riot  the  element  of 
violence  must  be  present ;  and  as  it  is  clear  that  the  offence  of 
unlawful  assembly  has,  from  the  first,  been  regarded  as  an  offence 
which  is  preparatory  to  or  contemplates  a  riot,5  it  cannot  be  com- 
mitted unless  both  the  purpose  of  the  assembly  is  illegal,6  and 
there  is  an  element  of  violence  in  the  illegal  purposes  for  which 
the  assembly  is  gathered  together.  It  follows  that  a  definition 
of  this  offence,  which  makes  it  include  an  assembly  which  con- 
templates the  commission  of  any  illegal  act,  is  not  historically  sound  ; 
and  it  is  the  better  opinion  that  it  is  not  good  law.7  Moreover, 
there  must  be  an  element  of  deliberate  purpose  ;  for  if  the  members 

1  Vol.  iv  497.  sVol.  v  198.  3  1  Ld.  Raym.  484. 

4  It  was  pointed  out  that,  "  if  the  indictment  had  been  that  the  defendant,  with 
divers  other  disturbers  of  the  peace  etc. ,  had  committed  this  riot  and  battery,  and 
the  verdict  had  been  as  in  this  case,  the  King  might  have  had  judgment,"  ibid. 

5  "  An  unlawful  assembly  is  when  three  or  more  assemble  themselves  together 
to  commit  a  riot  or  rout,  and  do  it  not,"  Coke,  Third  Instit.  176;  Hawkins,  P.C. 
Bk.  i  c.  65  §  9 ;  vol.  v  198. 

"Thus  an  assembly  of  a  man's  friends  in  his  house  merely  for  purposes  of  de- 
fence is  an  assembly  for  a  legal  purpose,  Y.B.  21  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  50  ;  Semayne's 
Case  (1605)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  91b  ;  Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  i  c.  65  §  10 ;  but  the  purpose  of 
such  an  assembly  must  be  strictly  defensive — "  si  on  fuit  menace  que  si  il  vient  a  tel 
marche,  ou  in  tiel  lieu,  il  sera  batte  la;  en  ceo  cas  il  ne  puit  assemble  des  gens  de 
luy  assister  d'aller  la  in  saufgard  de  sa  personne,  purceque  il  ne  besoigne  de  aller  la, 
et  il  puit  avoir  remedy  per  surete  de  paix,"  Y.B.  21  Hy.  VII.  Mich.  pi.  50  per 
Fineux,  C.J. ;  and  other  authorities  cited  lay  down  the  same  law. 

7  Vol.  v  198 ;  Y.B.  3  Hy.  VII.  Hil.  pi.  1 ;  Marowe's  Reading,  Putnam,  Oxford 
Studies  vol.  vii.  340-341 ;  Kenny,  op.  cit.  281 ;  Dicey,  Law  of  the  Constitution  (7th  ed.) 
500.  The  source  of  the  error  was  perhaps  Blackstone,  who,  adapting  Coke's  defini- 
tion of  a  riot  to  an  unlawful  assembly,  says  that  it  is  "  when  three  or  more  do  assemble 
themselves  together  to  do  an  unlawful  act,  as  to  pull  down  enclosures,  to  destroy  a 
warren,  and  the  game  therein  ;  and  part  without  doing  it  or  making  any  motion 
towards  it  "  ;  the  qualification  appears  in  the  illustrations,  but  it  is  not  explicitly  stated. 


326  CRIME  AND  TORT 

of  a  lawful  assembly  suddenly  fall  out  and  come  to  blows,  it  was 
settled,  as  early  as  I  503,  that  those  falling  out  are  guilty  of  an 
affray,  and  that  no  guilt  attaches  to  the  other  persons  attending 
the  assembly.1 

Coke  had  limited  somewhat  narrowly  the  sort  of  violent  wrong- 
doing which  an  assembly  must  contemplate  in  order  to  make  it 
an  unlawful  assembly.  He  defines  it  simply  as  "when  three  or 
more  assemble  themselves  together  to  commit  a  riot  or  rout  and 
doit  not";2  and  Blackstone  simply  repeats  Coke.3  But,  before 
Blackstone's  time,  it  was  coming  to  be  the  general  opinion  that 
this  definition  was  too  narrow,  i  t  was  coming  to  be  thought  that 
account  must  be  taken,  not  only  of  the  purpose  of  the  meeting,  but 
of  its  character  ;  and  that,  if  it  was  of  a  character  which  would  in- 
spire the  average  citizen  with  reasonable  fear,  it  might  be  held  to 
be  an  unlawful  assembly.  Marowe  had  put  forward  this  view  as 
early  as  1503  ;4  and  it  came  into  favour  during  the  seventeenth 
century.  There  was  some  slight  authority  for  it  in  precedents  of 
1566  and  161 7  cited  in  a  Star  Chamber  case  of  1617;5  it  was 
more  distinctly  asserted  by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  1708  ;(!  and  was  clearly 
stated  by  Hawkins  a  few  years  later.7  The  later  history  of  the 
development  of  this  offence  is  mainly  concerned  with  working  out 
the  consequences  of  this  aspect  of  the  offence ;  and  of  establish- 
ing criteria  to  distinguish  between  the  cases  when  a  meeting  can 
be  held  to  inspire  this  fear,  and  so  be  an  unlawful  assembly,  and 
the  cases  when  the  fear,  being  inspired  only  by  the  unlawful  acts 


1  Marowe's  Reading,  Putnam,  Oxford  Studies  vii  340;  "if  several  are  assembled 
lawfully  without  any  evil  intent,  and  an  affray  happens,  none  are  guilty  but  such  as 
act ;  but  if  the  assembly  was  originally  unlawful,  the  act  of  one  is  imputable  to  all," 
R.  v.  Ellis  (1708)  2  Sa!k.  595 /><r  Holt,  C.J. 

2  Third  Instit.  176. 

3  Comm.  iv  146. 

4  "  Item  le  maner  de  le  fesaunce  de  le  assemble  poet  faire  une  Riott  lou  assemble 
fut  loiall  devant ;  sicome  home  que  entendj  de  aler  al  cessions  ou  merkett  et  vient 
en  harnes  et  ceux  servantes  aussi  ove  luy  en  harnes,  et  uncore  paraventur  son  entent 
ne  fut  de  faire  ascun  Riott,  mes  le  maner  de  luy  face  le  Riott  pur  le  presens  del  people," 
op.  cit.  340. 

5  Howard  v.  Bell  and  Others,  Hob.  91 ;  in  that  case  tenants,  having  a  common 
interest,  had  assembled  together  to  maintain  their  title  ;  the  court  inclined  to  the  view 
that  this  was  lawful ;  but  the  Lord  Chancellor  cited  a  case  of  1566  where,  in  a  similar 
case,  a  riot  had  resulted ;  it  was  not  proved  that  the  defendants  had  been  concerned  in 
the  riot;  one  Bell  was  fined  for  assembling  the  tenants,  and  "Hodson  another  tenant 
was  also  punished  for  being  present  at  that  assembly,  and  the  event  of  such  an  assembly 
is  in  no  man's  power  to  moderate." 

8  R.  v.  Soley  2  Salk.  594 ;  at  p.  595  it  is  said  that,  "  the  Chief  Justice  thought  an 
assembly  might  meet  together  with  such  circumstances  of  terror  as  to  be  a  riot.  He 
called  it  a  kind  of  assault  upo.i  the  people." 

7"  But  this  seems  to  be  much  too  narrow  a  definition ;  for  any  meeting  whatso- 
ever of  great  numbers  of  people  with  such  circumstances  of  terror,  as  cannot  but 
endanger  the  public  peace,  and  raise  fears  and  jealousies  among  the  king's  subjects, 
seems  properly  to  be  called  an  unlawful  assembly  ;  for  no  one  can  foresee  what  may 
be  the  event  of  such  an  assembly,"  P.C.  Bk  i  c.  65  §  9. 


OFFENCES  COGNATE  TO  TREASON  327 

of  strangers  to  the  meeting,  will  not  make  the  meeting  an  unlawful 
assembly.1 

The  suggestion  that  a  meeting  is  an  unlawful  assembly,  if  it 
meets  with  intent  to  incite  disaffection  to  the  government  as  by 
law  established,  does  not  seem  to  have  been  made  in  England  till 
nearly  the  middle  of  the  nineteenth  century.2  Generally,  it  would 
seem,  the  members  of  such  an  assembly  would  be  indictable  for 
conspiracy ;  but,  as  Dicey  suggests,  they  might  be  indicted  for 
this  offence  "if  the  circumstances  of  the  time  were  such  that  the 
seditious  proceedings  at  the  meeting  would  be  likely*  to  endanger 
the  public  peace."3 

The  growth  of  the  law  as  to  the  offence  of  unlawful  assembly 
has  thus  been  a  comparatively  late  development.  We  may  per- 
haps find  a  reason  for  this  in  the  history  of  that  aspect  of  the  law 
as  to  riot  with  which  I  am  about  to  deal. 

(ii)  The  relation  between  the  repeal  of  the  earlier  legislation 
on  the  subject  of  riot  to  the  distinction  between  riot  and  treason. 

We  have  seen  that  a  statute  of  I  549-50 4  provided  that,  if 
twelve  or  more  persons  assembled  together  to  make  a  riot  with 
the  object  of  killing  or  imprisoning  a  Privy  Councillor,  or  of  un- 
lawfully altering  the  laws  established  by  Parliament ;  and  if  they 
remained  together  for  one  hour  after  a  summons  to  disperse,  all 
so  remaining  should  be  guilty  of  treason  ;  and  the  same  provision 
was  made  for  assemblies  of  forty  persons  or  more,  who  remained 
together  for  two  hours  and  upwards,  for  purpose  of  committing 
certain  other  traitorous  rebellious  or  felonious  acts.  It  was  also 
provided  that  those  taking  part  in  certain  other  riotous  assemblies, 
and  not  dispersing  after  due  notice,  should  be  guilty  of  felony ; 
and  that  those  who  summoned,  procured,  moved,  or  stirred  any  such 
assemblies  should  be  guilty  of  the  same  offence.  We  have  seen 
that  in  1 5 53  3  the  offences  which  were  made  treason  under  this 
Act  were  reduced  to  felony ;  that  this  enactment  was  renewed  in 
1558;6  and  that  it  remained  in  force  till  the  end  of  Elizabeth's 
reign,  when  it  expired." 

It  is  clear  that  these  Acts  hit  most  cases  of  riot  and  unlawful 
assembly.  While  they  were  in  force,  therefore,  there  was  not  much 
need  to  invoke  the  assistance  of  the  common  law.  Moroever,  any 
other  cases  could  be  and  generally  were  dealt  with  by  the  Star 

1  Dicey,  Law  of  the  Constitution  (7th  ed.)  500-504. 

2  "  Any  meeting  of  her  Majesty's  subjects  which  a  party  procures  to  assemble  for 
the  purpose  of  addressing  a  seditious  speech  ...  a  meeting  called  for  that  purpose 
and  used  for  that  purpose  is  an  unlawful  meeting,"  R.  v.  Ernest  Jones  (1848)  6 
S.T.N. S.  at  p.  816  per  Wilde,  C.J. ;  a  similar  ruling  by  the  same  judge  was  given 
in  R.  v.  Fussell  (1848)  ibid  at  p.  764. 

3  Law  of  the  Constitution  (7th  ed.)  501  n.  1. 

4  3,  4  Edward  VI.  c  5  ;  voL  iv  497.  5  1  Mary  Sess.  2  c.  12  ;  vol.  iv  497. 
6  1  Elizabeth  c.  16.  ?  Vol.  iv  497  n.  9. 


328  CRIME  AND  TORT 

Chamber.  When  these  Acts  expired,  political  conditions  made  it 
very  unlikely  that  Parliament  would  pass  any  Act  giving  to  the 
crown  powers  which  might  easily  be  used  against  its  political  oppo- 
nents ;  and  the  Star  Chamber  was  fully  competent  to  deal  with  any 
ordinary  case  of  riot  or  unlawful  assembly.  But  at  the  Restor- 
ation the  courts  were  faced  with  a  new  set  of  political  conditions. 
The  Star  Chamber  had  been  abolished,  and  the  courts  were  there- 
fore obliged  to  use  their  common  law  powers.  It  was  no  doubt 
because  their  powers  were  inadequate,  that  we  see  in  this  period 
a  development  of  the  constructive  extension  of  the  clause  of 
Edward  I II. 's  statute  of  treasons,  which  made  the  levying  of  war 
against  the  king  treason.1  For  if  a  riot  could  be  brought  within 
the  sphere  of  treason,  not  only  was  the  punishment  much  more 
severe,  but  also,  as  we  shall  see,2  the  common  law  powers  of 
magistrates  soldiers  and  others  to  suppress  it  were  greater.  But 
the  consideration  of  these  cases  necessarily  involved  a  closer  de- 
finition of  the  essential  features  of  the  offence  of  riot.  And  it  is 
therefore,  in  this  period,  that  the  modern  definition  of  this  offence  is 
ascertained.  In  the  first  place,  the  object  of  the  riot  must  be 
merely  a  private  object.  "  A  recovers  possession  against  B  of  a 
house  etc.  in  a  real  action  or  in  an  ejectione  firmae,  and  a  writ  of 
seisin  or  possession  goes  to  the  sheriff.  B  holds  his  house  against 
the  sheriff,  with  force,  and  assembles  persons  with  weapons  for 
that  purpose,  who  keep  the  house  with  a  strong  hand  against  the 
sheriff,  tho'  assisted  with  the  posse  comitatus.  This  is  no  treason 
either  in  B  or  his  accomplices,  but  only  a  great  riot  and  mis- 
demeanour." 3  In  the  second  place,  if  the  aspect  of  the  assembly 
was  not  warlike,  it  could  only  be  a  riotous  assembly,  and  its  acts 
of  violence  could  only  amount  to  a  riot.  To  make  the  acts  of  a 
riotous  assembly  treasonable,  "  it  must  be  such  an  assembly  as 
carries  with  it  speciem  belli,  as  if  they  ride  or  march  vexilis  ex- 
plicatis,  or  if  they  be  formed  into  companies,  or  furnished  with 
military  officers,  or  if  they  are  armed  with  military  weapons.  .  .  . 
and  are  so  circumstanced  that  it  may  reasonably  be  concluded 
they  are  in  a  posture  of  war,  which  circumstances  are  so  various, 
that  it  is  hard  to  define  them  all  particularly."4 

It  is  clear  from  this  passage  that  the  line  between  a  mere  riot 
and  a  constructive  levying  of  war  was  fine.  As  we  have  seen,  it 
caused  differences  of  judicial  opinion ; 5  and  as,  in  many  cases,  the 
penalty  was  out  of  all  proportion  to  the  offence  with  which  in- 
dividual rioters  were  charged,  it  shocked  the  public  conscience. 
It  was  for  this  reason  that  in  17146  the  present  Riot  Act  was 
passed,  which  re-enacted  in  a  modified  form  the  provisions  of  the 

1  Above  319-320.  2  Below  330-331.  3  Hale,  P.C.  i  146.  4  Ibid  150. 

6  Above  319-320.  6 1  George  I.  st.  2  c.  5  ;  Bl.  Comm.  iv  143. 


OFFENCES  COGNATE  TO  TREASON  329 

Acts  which  had  been  in  force  during  Mary  and  Elizabeth's  reigns ; 
and  we  have  seen  that  it  was  due  to  this  enactment  that  the  govern- 
ment generally  avoided  recourse  to  this  species  of  constructive 
treason.1  This  statute  in  effect  provides  that,  if  twelve  or  more 
persons  are  unlawfully  assembled  to  the  disturbance  of  the  peace, 
and  a  mayor,  sheriff,  or  justice  of  the  peace  command  them  to  dis- 
perse, and  they  continue  together  for  one  hour  after  such  com- 
mand, all  so  continuing  are  guilty  of  felony  ;  and  those  who  after- 
wards disperse  the  assembly  are  indemnified  for  the  consequences 
of  any  violence  which  they  may  employ. 

This  Act  has  generally  been  found  sufficient  to  deal  with  un- 
lawful assemblies,  the  demeanour  of  which  is  obviously  threatening, 
and  with  actual  riots.  It  was  the  large  increase  in  meetings  held 
to  advocate  public  objects,  which  occurred  at  the  end  of  the 
eighteenth  and  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  centuries,  which 
has  led  to  the  development  of  the  law  as  to  unlawful  assembly, 
which  I  have  already  noticed.2  Their  demeanour  was  generally 
not  obviously  threatening ;  and  they  were  not  assembled  with 
the  direct  object  of  committing  a  riot.  In  many  cases,  however, 
it  was  fairly  clear  that  a  riot  might  easily  result  from  their 
meeting.  But  to  them  the  provisions  of  the  Riot  Act  were  not 
immediately  applicable ;  and  therefore  they  have  caused  not  only 
a  development  of  the  law  relating  to  unlawful  assemblies,  but  also 
some  reconsideration  of  the  law  as  to  powers  of  the  authorities  in 
dealing  with  these  assemblies.3 

(iii)  The  liabilities  of  rioters,  and  the  measures  which  may  or 
ought  to  be  taken  for  the  suppression  of  riots,  or  the  dispersal  of 
unlawful  assemblies. 

The  law  as  to  the  liability  of  rioters  who,  in  the  course  of  their 
riotous  conduct,  committed  a  felony,  was  strict  and  satisfactory. 
It  was  established,  as  early  as  Edward  III.'s  reign,  that  all  were 
equally  liable  for  the  felony.4  "Note  also,"  says  Dalton,5  "that 
if  divers  persons  come  in  one  company  to  do  any  unlawful  thing, 
as  to  kill,  rob  or  beat  a  man,  or  to  commit  a  riot,  or  to  do  any 
other  trespass,  and  one  of  them  thereof  kill  a  man,  this  shall  be 
adjudged  murder  in  them  all,  that  are  present  of  that  party  abetting 
him,  and  consenting  to  the  act,  or  ready  to  aid  him,  altho'  they 
did  but  look  on."  Hale  quotes  this  passage  from  Dalton  with 
approval,  and  cites  a  case  of  1675  m  which  this  rule  of  law  was 
restated.6  But,  if  no  felony  was  committed,  the  law  was  not  equally 

1  Above  320.  2  Above  326. 

3  Dicey,  Law  of  the  Constitution  (7th  ed)  504-512. 

4  Fitz.  Ab.  Corone  pi.  350  (3  Ed.  III.). 

5  Cited  Hale,  P.C.  i  441. 

6  Ibid  462-463  ;  cp.  Mackalley's  Case  (1612)  9  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  67b. 


330  CRIME  AND  TORT 

satisfactory.  Each  individual  rioter  was  only  liable  for  a  mis- 
demeanour, whatever  damage  he  did  ;  and  thus  the  technical  dis- 
tinction between  felony  and  misdemeanour  tended  sometimes  to 
lighten  unduly  the  liability  of  the  rioters. 

The  same  cause  tended  also  to  hamper  the  authorities  in  sup- 
pressing riots,  or  in  dispersing  unlawful  assemblies  ;  and  to  render 
the  position  of  the  ordinary  citizen,  who  helped  to  suppress  or 
disperse  them,  somewhat  dubious.  It  was  largely  for  this  reason 
that  the  provisions  of  the  Riot  Act 1  were  needed.  This  will  be 
clear  if  we  look  at  the  rules  on  this  matter,  some  of  which,  though 
elaborated  and  extended  in  this  period,  originated  in  the  Middle 
Ages. 

In  the  sixteenth  century  every  citizen  was  justified  in  taking 
all  reasonable  means  to  put  a  stop  to  breaches  of  the  peace  com- 
mitted in  his  presence. 2  He  was  therefore  justified  in  intervening 
to  help  to  suppress  a  riot  or  to  disperse  an  unlawful  assembly. 
But,  if  no  felony  had  been  committed,  he  could  only  use  reason- 
able force  for  this  purpose ;  and  to-day 3  as  in  the  thirteenth 
century,4  he  must  at  his  peril  hit  the  mean  between  excess  and 
defect.5  On  the  other  hand,  if  a  felony  has  been  committed,  all 
the  rioters  are,  as  we  have  seen,6  guilty  of  felony ;  and  it  is  the 
duty  of  every  citizen  to  apprehend  the  felon.7  If,  therefore,  in 
such  a  case  a  rioter  is  killed  in  resisting  apprehension,  the 
homicide  is  justifiable.8  A  fortiori,  the  same  rule  applies  if  some 
duly  constituted  officer  of  the  law  has  raised  the  posse  comitatus, 
or  has  called  for  assistance  to  suppress  a  riot  or  to  disperse  an 
unlawful  assembly,  and  a  private  person  goes  to  his  help,  and  kills 

1 1  George  I.  st.  2  c.  5. 

2  Marowe,  Oxford  Studies  vii  336 ;  Coke,  Third  Instit.  158 ;  R.  v.  Pinney  (1832) 
3  S.T.N.S.  at  p.  4.  Coke  cites  no  authority,  though  in  fact  his  statement  is  justified 
by  the  resolution  of  the  judges  in  the  Case  of  Armes  (1597)  Pop.  121 ;  the  rule  may 
well  be  a  sixteenth-century  extension  of  the  duty  to  arrest  felons,  vol.  iii  599-601 ; 
Maitland  says,  "  we  may  strongly  suspect  that  in  general  the  only  persons  whom  it  is 
safe  to  arrest  are  felons,  and  that  one  leaves  oneself  open  to  an  action,  or  even  an 
appeal,  of  false  imprisonment  if  one  takes  as  a  felon  a  man  who  has  done  no  felony," 
P.  and  M.  ii  580-581 ;  this  is  justified  by  Marowe's  statement,  loc.  cit.,  that  though  a 
man  could  stop  an  affray,  he  had  no  action  if  he  were  hurt,  but  that  those  guilty  of  the 
affray  had  an  action  if  he  hurt  them;  and  see  Stephen,  H.C.L.  i  193  ;  in  fact  the  right 
to  arrest  felons  merely  on  suspicion  seems  to  be  denied  in  42  Ass.  pi.  5  ;  however,  it 
seems  to  be  admitted  in  Y.B.  11  Ed.  IV.  Trin.  pi.  8  that  a  private  person  may  arrest 
another  whom  he  suspects  of  felony;  and  in  Y.B.  10  Hy.  VII.  Pasch.  pi.  8  it  was  said 
that  if  A  had  wounded  B,  A  could  be  arrested,  till  it  could  be  known  whether  B  died 
of  the  stroke;  this  implies  a  power  to  arrest  for  an  act  which  was  not  ascertained  to  be 
felony ;  and  the  rule  stated  by  Coke  may  well  be  a  further  stage  in  the  extension  of 
these  precedents. 

s  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  283. 

4  "  The  ordinary  man  seems  to  have  been  expected  to  be  very  active  in  the 
pursuit  of  malefactors,  and  yet  to  act  at  his  peril,"  P.  and  M.  ii  581. 

5  In  R.  v.  Pinney  (1832)  3  S.T.N.S.  at  p.  510  Littledale,  J.,  speaking  of  the  duty 
of  a  magistrate  called  on  to  suppress  a  riot,  said,  "he  is  bound  to  hit  the  exact  line 
between  an  excess  and  doing  what  is  sufficient." 

u  Above  329.  7  Vol.  iii  599-600.  8  Hale,  P.C.  i  495. 


OFFENCES  COGNATE  TO  TREASON  331 

a  rioter  who  resists  the  attempt  to  apprehend  him.1  And  in  this 
case  it  would  seem  that  the  homicide  of  those  resisting  dispersal  or 
arrest  would,  prima  facie  at  any  rate,  be  justifiable,  even  though 
no  felony  had  been  committed. - 

Since  an  ordinary  citizen  might  be  made  liable  if  he  did  not 
help  to  suppress  a  riot  or  disperse  an  unlawful  assembly  when 
called  upon  to  do  so,  a  fortiori  an  official  could  be  made  liable  if 
he  neglected  this  duty.  And  just  as  statutes  had  added  to  the 
powers  of  officials  to  take  measures  to  arrest  rioters,3  so  other 
statutes  had  rendered  them  liable  to  special  penalties  if  the}' 
failed  in  their  duties.4  But  these  statutes  only  rendered  more 
explicit  the  common  law  principles ;  and  it  is  these  principles 
upon  which  the  modern  common  law  rests.5  The  erroneous  idea 
that  the  Riot  Act  had  somehow  modified  these  principles,  led  to 
the  failure  of  the  authorities  to  check  the  Lord  George  Gordon 
riots  in  their  initial  stage,  and  to  the  authoritative  correction  of 
this  error.6 

The  development  of  the  law  of  treason  during  this  period,  and 
of  offences  cognate  thereto,  represents  the  contribution  made  by 
the  common  law  to  the  maintenance  of  the  authority  of  the  state 
and  its  law.  Professor  Kenny  has  said  that  the  severity  of  the 
law  on  these  matters  was  largely  due  to  the  inadequacy  of  its 
powers  for  the  prevention  of  crime — an  inadequacy  which  was 
due  to  the  absence  of  efficient  police.  "  The  law  felt  its  parish 
constabulary  to  be  comparatively  powerless  to  prevent  any  offence 
that  involved  the  presence  of  a  plurality  of  offenders.  It  con- 
sequently attempted  to  supply  the  defect  by  very  comprehensive 
prohibitions  of  all  such  crimes."  "  This  is  true,  but  not  I  think 
the  whole  truth.  It  explains,  I  think,  the  rules  which  have  just 
been  discussed  as  to  the  measures  which  may  or  ought  to  be 
taken  by  officials  and  others  for  the  suppression  of  riots ;  and,  to 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  495. 

3  "  And  it  seems,  as  to  this  manner  of  killing  rioters,  that  resist  the  ministers  of 
justice  in  their  apprehending,  it  is  no  other  but  what  the  common  law  allows,  or  at 
least  what  the  statute  of  13  H.  4  cap.  7  implicitly  allows  to  two  justices  of  the  peace 
with  the  sheriff  or  undersheriff  of  the  county,  by  giving  them  power  to  raise  the  posse 
comitatus,  if  need  be,  and  to  arrest  the  rioters.  .  .  .  And  it  seems  the  same  law  is  for 
the  constable  of  a  vill  in  case  a  riot  happen  within  the  vill,"  Hale,  P.C.  i  495  ;  accord- 
ing to  Marowe,  Putnam,  Oxford  Studies,  vii  33S-339  the  sheriff  had,  apart  from  this  and 
other  statutes,  no  power  to  call  for  assistance — "  Quar  per  le  comen  ley  null  puit  com- 
maunder  les  homez  del  conte  de  aler  ove  luy  en  cest  cas  forsque  le  Roie  tantum ;  quar 
cest  commaundement  fut  entendue  une  sequestracion  de  loure  liberte." 

3  34  Edward  III.  c.  1 ;  17  Richard  II.  c.  8 ;  13  Henry  IV.  c.  7 ;  Hawkins,  P.C. 
Bk.  i  c.  65  §§  15-29. 

4  13  Henry  IV.  c.  7  ;  2  Henry  V.  c.  8  ;  19  Henry  VII.  c.  13. 

*  See  Tindal  C.J.'s  charge  to  the  grand  jury  at  the  opening  of  the  special  com- 
mission to  try  the  Bristol  rioters  in  1832,  3  S.T.N.S.  4-6. 
B  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  285.  "  Ibid  280. 


332  CRIME  AND  TORT 

some  small  extent,  it  perhaps  explains  the  severity  of  the  rules  as 
to  these  and  other  offences  cognate  to  treason.  But,  it  seems  to 
me,  the  severity  of  these  rules  admits  not  merely  of  explanation, 
but  of  a  justification,  which  is  as  much  applicable  to  the  present 
age  as  to  the  age  in  which  they  were  evolved. 

However  efficient  the  police  system  may  be,  a  neglect  to  deal 
severely  with  these  and  the  like  offences  of  a  seditious  kind  will 
speedily  undermine  the  authority  of  the  state  and  the  law ;  and, 
as  the  history  of  the  criminal  law  in  this  period  shows,  firm 
measures  of  suppression  will,  even  in  the  absence  of  an  adequate 
police  system,  vastly  diminish  their  power  for  evil.  More  really 
depends  on  the  spirit  which  animates  the  rulers  of  the  state  than 
upon  the  material  means  of  coercion  at  their  disposal.  If  a 
state  allows  its  subjects  too  large  a  freedom  to  express  opinions 
directly  hostile  to  its  authority,  and  too  large  a  power  to  combine  ; 
and,  if,  in  addition,  it  puts  the  most  formidable  of  these  combina- 
tions above  the  law ;  it  will  soon  sink  back  to  the  condition  in 
which  the  English  state  found  itself  at  the  time  of  the  Wars  of 
the  Roses.  It  will  soon  find  that  its  authority  is  small  in  com- 
parison with  that  of  its  over  mighty  subjects,  and  that  the  duty  of 
allegiance  to  it  is  held  to  be  of  small  account,  when  it  conflicts 
with  the  allegiance  exacted  by  these  usurpers  of  its  authority. 

In  fact,  the  history  of  the  law  of  treason  and  of  the  offences 
cognate  thereto,  shows  that  the  creation  and  preservation  of  a  law- 
abiding  instinct  is  as  difficult  to  maintain  as  it  is  easy  to  under- 
mine. This  work  can  only  be  successfully  accomplished  by  a  firm, 
a  far  seeing,  and  an  intelligent  administration  of  the  rules  designed 
to  safeguard  the  state  against  those  who  attempt,  from  whatever 
motives,  to  set  up  rivals  to  its  authority, — an  administration  of 
these  rules  which,  on  adequate  grounds,  is  not  afraid  to  be  cruel. 
As  I  have  already  pointed  out,1  the  more  firmly  the  law  is 
administered  on  these  lines,  the  less  need  there  will  be  for  cruelty ; 
for  the  state  will  cease  to  fear  its  criminals,  and  will  consequently 
feel  itself  able  to  be  generous.  It  was  largely  due  to  the  fact  that 
the  criminal  law  was  administered  on  these  lines  during  these  two 
centuries,  that,  at  the  end  of  this  period,  the  state  and  its  law  had 
emerged  supreme.  It  is  true  that  all  through  this  period  lawless- 
ness was  rampant.  But  the  measure  of  the  success  which  had 
been  achieved  in  dealing  with  this  lawlessness,  and  especially  with 
lawlessness  of  the  seditious  variety,  can  be  best  measured  by  the 
contrast  between  the  state  of  England  in  1 500  with  its  state  in 
1700.  At  the  latter  date  life  and  property  Were  far  more  secure, 
and  the  foundations  of  the  future  commercial  prosperity  of  the 
country  had  been  laid. 

1  Vol.  v  196. 


DEFAMATION  333 

That  this  result  had  been  attained  was  also  due  to  the  fact  that 
the  common  law  had  been  careful  to  guard  against  many  other 
offences,  which  were  almost  as  much  cognate  to  treason  as  those 
which  have  just  been  described.  We  shall  see  in  the  ensuing 
sections  that  its  rules  as  to  the  treatment  of  seditious  speeches  and 
writings,  as  to  conspiracy,  and,  to  some  extent,  the  rules  which 
imposed  legal  disabilities  upon  religious  nonconformists,  all  helped 
towards  the  attainment  of  this  result ;  for  they  all  helped  to  form 
a  consistent  public  opinion  upon  such  fundamental  matters  as  the 
sanctity  of  the  law,  the  protection  of  property,  and  the  sacredness 
of  contract  Both  the  experience  of  the  Commonwealth  period, 
and  the  experience  of  our  own  days,  prove  that  the  unlimited 
tolerance  of  all  opinions  tends  to  undermine  all  these  fundamental 
principles  upon  which  the  stability  of  the  state,  and,  therefore,  of 
civilization  itself,  depend. 

§  2.  Defamation 

The  wrong  of  defamation  is  sometimes  a  crime  pure  and 
simple,  sometimes  a  tort  pure  and  simple,  and  sometimes  it  can  be 
treated  either  as  a  crime  or  a  tort  at  the  option  of  the  injured 
person.  Defamation  is  a  crime  when  it  consists  of  the  publication 
seditious  obscene  or  blasphemous  speeches,  or  the  publication  of 
of  seditious  obscene  or  blasphemous  writings,  or  the  utterance  of 
writings  or  the  utterance  of  speeches  which  directly  incite  to  a 
breach  of  the  peace.  Defamation  is  a  tort  when  it  consists  of  the 
publication  of  writings,  or  the  utterance  of  speeches,  which  hold 
another  person  up  to  hatred  contempt  or  ridicule,  provided,  in  the 
case  of  speeches,  special  damage  can  be  proved  or  is  presumed. 
Defamation  can  be  treated  either  as  a  crime  or  tort  at  the  option 
of  the  injured  person,  if  it  consists  of  the  publication  of  writings 
which  hold  him  up  to  hatred  contempt  or  ridicule.1 

There  is  nothing  anomalous  in  the  fact  that  defamation  is  thus 
treated  sometimes  as  a  crime,  sometimes  as  a  tort,  and  sometimes 
as  either  a  crime  or  a  tort ;  for  it  is  obvious  that  defamatory 
writings  or  speeches  may,  according  to  their  contents,  either  (i) 
affect  the  stability  or  the  peace  of  the  state  or  the  morals  of  its 
subjects,  or  (ii)  cause  loss  of  reputation  or  pecuniary  loss  to  an 
individual,  or  (iii)  be  both  dangerous  to  the  peace  of  the  state  and 
harmful  to  an  individual.  In  Roman  law  some  forms  of  defama- 
tion could  be  regarded  either  as  delicts  or  as  crimes  ;a  and,  if  no 

1  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  305-314. 

2  Girard,  Droit  Romain  393 — "  Le  droit  imperial  continua  le  mouvement  com- 
mence par  la  loi  Cornelia  et  donna,  finalement  dans  tous  les  cas,  a  la  victime  de 
l'injure,  le  droit  de  choisir  entre  Taction  d'injures  et  une  punition  physique  infligee  au 
coupable  extra  ordinem  par  le  magistrat  que  le  jurisconsult  recent  Hermogenien  re- 
pre^ente  comme  choisie  d'ordinaire  de  son  temps." 


334  CRIME  AND  TORT 

specific  person  was  defamed,  the  defamation  could  only  be 
criminally  prosecuted.1  Nor  is  there  anything  anomalous  in  the 
manner  in  which  English  law  treats  seditious  obscene  or  blas- 
phemous writings  or  speeches,  or  writings  or  speeches  which 
directly  incite  to  breaches  of  the  peace.  What  is  anomalous  is 
the  manner  in  which  it  treats  defamation,  when  it  consists  of 
writings  or  speeches  which  hold  up  another  person  to  hatred  con- 
tempt or  ridicule.  In  this  part  of  the  law  a  sharp  line  is  drawn 
between  written  and  spoken  defamation,  which  puts  them  into 
two  very  different  categories.  Other  systems  of  law  sometimes 
provide  that  the  penalty  shall  be  increased  if  the  defamation  is 
written.2  No  other  system  treats  what  is  essentially  the  same 
offence  in  two  essentially  different  ways. 

In  English  law  the  written  defamation  of  another  is  a  libel 
which  is  actionable  per  se,  and  can  be  treated  at  the  option  of  the 
injured  person  as  either  a  crime  or  a  tort.  On  the  other  hand, 
spoken  defamation  of  another  can  only  be  a  tort,  and  will  only  be 
a  tort  if  the  words  fall  into  a  limited  class  of  cases  in  which  words 
are  actionable  per  se,  or  if  they  cause  temporal  loss.  The  result 
is,  as  it  has  been  well  said,  "  absurd  in  theory,  and  very  often 
mischievous  in  its  practical  operation."3  It  is  only  partially 
remedied  by  the  growth  of  the  specific  tort  of  slander  of  title,'1  and 
of  the  analogous  tort  of  maliciously  uttering  falsehoods  which 
damage  a  plaintiff's  business.5  It  is  clear  that  this  anomalous 
state  of  the  law  can  only  be  explained  by  the  history  of  the  way 
in  which  the  law  on  this,  and  other  branches  of  the  law  of  defam- 
ation, has  grown  up. 

Some  of  the  leading  principles  and  characteristics  of  the 
modern  law  of  defamation  began  to  take  shape  during  the  last 
half  of  the  seventeenth  century.  The  shape  which  they  took  is 
the  product  of  the  earlier  development  of  this  branch  of  the  law. 
Of  that  earlier  development  I  have  already  said  something.6  But 
in  order  to  understand  its  modern  development,  a  brief  recapitu- 
lation is  necessary. 

The  primitive  codes  of  the  Anglo-Saxons 7  and  other  Teutonic 


1  "  Quod  senatus-consultum  necessarium  est,  cum  nomen  adjectum  non  est  ejus, 
in  quern  factum  est :  tunc  ei,  quia  difficilis  probatio  est,  voluit  senatus  publica  quaes- 
tione  rem  vindicari.  Ceterum  si  nomen  adjectum  est,  et  jure  communi  injuriarum  agi 
poterit :  nee  enim  prohibendus  est  privato  agere  judicio,  quod  publico  judicio  prae- 
judicatur,  quia  ad  privatam  causam  pertinet,"  Dig.  47.  10.  6  ;  cp.  Code  9.  36. 

2  See  e.g.  the  provisions  of  the  German  law  cited  L.Q.R.  x  160  ;  and  the  Scotch 
law  follows  the  same  rule,  ibid  161. 

3  Veeder,  The  History  of  Defamation,  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  446. 
*  Below  351-352. 

5  Below  352. 

6  Vol.  ii  366,  382-383;  vol.  iii  409-411  ;  vol.  v  205-212. 

7  Vol.  ii  382  n.  11. 


DEFAMATION  335 

races,1  like  the  primitive  code  of  the  Twelve  Tables,2  punished 
defamatory  words ;  and  in  later  days  the  manorial  and  other 
local  courts  gave  remedies  for  this  offence.3  But  the  provisions  of 
the  Anglo-Saxon  laws  on  this  matter  have  no  continuous  history  ; 
and  the  jurisdiction  of  the  manorial  and  other  local  courts  decayed. 
Unless  the  defamation  was  of  a  sort  which  came  within  the 
statutes  which  created  the  offence  of  scandalum  magnatum,4  the 
mediaeval  common  law  gave  no  remedy.  For  all  other  defamation 
the  suitor  was  obliged  to  go  to  the  ecclesiastical  courts.  It  was 
not  till  the  beginning  of  the  sixteenth  century  that  the  common 
law  courts  began  to  compete  with  the  ecclesiastical  courts  in  this 
field  of  jurisdiction,  by  allowing  an  action  on  the  case  for  defama- 
tion.5 As  usually  happened  when  the  common  law  courts  and  the 
ecclesiastical  courts  came  into  conflict,  the  common  law  courts 
soon  deprived  the  ecclesiastical  courts  of  the  greater  part  of  their 
jurisdiction.  This  was  due  partly  to  the  fact  that  the  common 
law  courts  prohibited  the  ecclesiastical  courts  from  entertaining 
any  suit  for  defamation,  unless  the  defamatory  words  had  charged 
the  plaintiff  with  some  offence  of  exclusively  ecclesiastical  cog- 
nisance ;  and  partly  to  the  popularity  of  the  common  law  remedy 
of  damages,  as  compared  with  the  merely  ecclesiastical  penalty 
which  the  ecclesiastical  courts  could  inflict.'5  In  fact,  so  popular 
was  the  common  law  remedy,  that  the  common  law  courts  found 
themselves  obliged  to  take  measures  to  diminish  the  flood  of 
litigation  which  threatened  to  overwhelm  them.7 

Since  the  common  law  remedy  was  an  action  on  the  case, 
damage  was  the  gist  of  the  action.  And  damage  was  construed 
in  a  narrow  proprietary  sense.  As  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  said,8  "  the 
law  went  wrong  from  the  beginning  in  making  the  damage  and 
not  the  insult  the  cause  of  the  action."  But  this  defect  was  in- 
herent in  the  form  of  action  by  which  alone  redress  could  be 
given ;  and  there  is  no  doubt  that  the  inherent  defect  of  this  way 
of  looking  at  this  wrong  was  aggravated  by  the  measures  which 
the  courts  took  to  stem  this  tide  of  litigation.  We  shall  see  that, 
in  order  to  discourage  litigants,  they  insisted  on  construing  words, 
whenever  possible,  as  innocent ;  and  that,  in  their  endeavours  to 
give  them  a  "mitior  sensus,"  they  construed  them  with  the  same 

1  "  Even  the  rude  Lex  Salica  decrees  that  if  one  calls  a  man  '  wolf '  or  '  hare  '  one 
must  pay  him  three  shillings,  while  if  one  calls  a  woman  '  harlot,'  and  cannot  prove 
the  truth  of  the  charge,  one  must  pay  her  forty-five  shillings.  ...  In  the  Norman 
custumal  it  is  written  that  the  man  who  has  falsely  called  another  '  thief  or  '  man- 
slayer  '  must  pay  damages,  and,  holding  his  nose  with  his  fingers,  must  publicly 
confess  himself  a  liar,"  P.  and  M.  ii  536. 

2  '*  Nostrae  contra  xii  tab.  cum  perpaucas  res  capite  sanxissent,  in  his  hanc  quoque 
sanciendam  putaverunt :  si  quis  occentavisset  sive  carmen  condidisset,  quod  infamiam 
faceret  flagitiumve  alteri,"  Cicero  De  Rep.  iv  10,  12. 

3  Vol.  ii  382-383.  *  Vol.  iii  409-410.  «  Ibid  411 ;  vol.  v  205-208. 
■  Ibid  206.                          7  Ibid  ;  below  353  seqq.           s  Torts  (r2th  ed.)  324. 


336  CRIME  AND  TORT 

strictness  as  they  were  accustomed  to  construe  writs  or  pleadings, 
with  results  which  were  often  absurd  and  sometimes  unjust.1 

But,  while  the  development  of  the  tort  of  defamation  was  thus 
being  warped  by  the  action  of  the  common  law  courts,  a  wholly 
new  conception  of  this  offence  was  being  developed  in  the  court 
of  Star  Chamber.  We  have  seen  that  the  Council  and  the  Star 
Chamber  had,  in  the  interests  of  the  peace  and  security  of  the 
state,  assumed  a  strict  control  over  the  press.2  Naturally  the 
Star  Chamber  assumed  jurisdiction  in  all  cases  in  which  its  rules 
on  this  matter  had  been  infringed ;  and  this  led  it  to  regard  de- 
famation as  a  crime.  Borrowing  perhaps  from  the  Roman  law  as 
to  Libella  Famosa,3  it  treated  libels  both  upon  officials  and  private 
persons  as  crimes.  The  former  were  seditious  libels,  and  directly 
affected  the  security  of  the  state.  The  latter  obviously  led  to 
breaches  of  the  peace.  On  the  same  principle  it  dealt  with 
seditious  words.4  But  we  have  seen  that  in  this  case  its  practice 
was  not  always  consistent ;  for,  at  any  rate  in  the  case  of  words 
which  were  not  seditious,  their  truth  was  allowed  to  be  pleaded  as 
a  defence — a  defence  which  is,  as  we  have  seen,  wholly  out  of 
place  if  defamation  is  regarded  as  a  crime.8 

When  the  Star  Chamber  was  abolished,  the  law  of  defamation 
thus  consisted  of  two  very  divergent  parts.  In  the  first  place, 
there  was  the  body  of  law  developed  in  the  Star  Chamber,  which 
regarded  defamation  as  a  crime ;  and,  in  the  second  place,  there 
was  the  body  of  law  developed  round  the  common  law  action  on 
the  case,  which  regarded  defamation  as  a  tort.  The  common  law 
judges  after  the  Restoration  took  over  the  law  as  developed  by  the 
Star  Chamber,  and  further  developed  it  on  similar  lines.  They 
also  further  developed  the  conception  of  the  tort  of  defamation. 
Naturally  these  cognate  bodies  of  law,  being  developed  by  the 
same  tribunals,  exercised  a  reciprocal  influence  on  one  another ; 
and  our  modern  law  is  the  result.  The  history  of  its  construction 
during  this  period  I  shall  trace  under  the  two  heads  of  Defama- 
tion as  a  Crime,  and  Defamation  as  a  Tort. 

Defamation  as  a  Crime 

The  two  main  varieties  of  the  crime  of  defamation  were  dis- 
tinguished by  Coke  in  the  case  De  Libellis  Famosis.6  It  can  be 
committed  either  against  a  private  person,  or  against  a  magistrate 
or  other  public  person  ;  and  the  latter  is  the  much  more  serious 
offence,  "  for  it  concerns  not  only  the  breach  of  the  peace  but 
the  scandal  of  Government."     The  first  variety  can  be  quickly 

1  Below  355-356  ;  vol.  v  206.  2  Vol.  vi  367-370.  3  Vol.  v  208. 

4  Ibid  211.  5  Ibid  211-212.  6(i6o6)  5  Co.  Rep.  125a;  vol.  v  208, 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  CRIME  337 

disposed  of.  It  was  defined  by  the  common  law  courts  and 
punished,  just  as  the  Star  Chamber  had  defined  and  punished 
it.1  The  chief  addition  made  by  the  common  law  courts  to  the 
earlier  law  was  the  definite  settlement  of  the  rule,  foreshadowed 
in  the  earlier  law,-  that  mere  spoken  words  defamatory  to  a  I 
private  person  cannot  be  treated  as  a  crime.3  We  shall  see  that  I 
this  decision  is  important  in  the  history  of  defamation  as  a 
tort ;  for  it  probably  had  a  good  deal  to  do  with  creating  the 
unfortunate  distinction  between  the  torts  of  libel  and  slander.4 
It  is  the  second  variety  of  libels  which  is  the  most  important, 
and  it  is  the  law  as  to  these  libels  which  was  the  most  developed 
during  this  period.  Naturally,  as  we  shall  see,  some  of  the 
principles  thus  developed  helped  to  elucidate  some  of  the  incidents 
of  the  first  variety  of  the  crime  of  libel. 

The  crime  of  publishing  defamatory  statements  against  the 
government  falls  under  several  heads.  It  may  be  committed  by 
publishing  seditious  writings  or  by  speaking  seditious  words,  or 
by  publishing  blasphemous  or  obscene  writings,  or  by  speaking 
blasphemous  or  obscene  words,  or  by  uttering  words  which  incite 
directly  to  a  breach  of  the  peace.5 

With  the  history  of  the  law  as  to  blasphemous  writings  and 
speeches  I  shall  deal  later.6  With  regard  to  obscene  writings  and 
speeches,  Holt,  C.J.,  seemed  to  think  that  this  was  matter  for 
the  ecclesiastical  courts,  and  was  not  remediable  by  indictment ; " 
but  a  few  years  later  this  opinion  was  reversed,  and  the  law  was 
placed  on  its  modern  basis  by  the  decision  in  R.  v.  Cur/.s  With 
regard  to  words  which  tend  to  a  breach  of  the  peace,  Holt,  C.J., 
ruled  in  R.  v.  Lang-ley0  that  "words  that  directly  tend  to  breach 
of  the  peace  may  be  indictable ;  but  otherwise  to  encourage 
indictments  for  words  would  make  them  as  uncertain  as  actions 
for  words  are."  M  It  is  the  history  of  the  law  as  to  seditious 
writings  and  words  which  is  the  most  important.  The  history 
of  the  manner  in  which  it  was  shaped  by  the  common  law  courts, 
after  they  had  taken  over  this  jurisdiction  from  the  Star  Chamber, 
I  must  now  relate. 

Stephen  has  pointed  out u  that  the  view  which  the  law  takes 

1  See  R.  v.  Beare  (i6gg)  i  Ld.  Raym.  414 ;  S.C.  2  Salk.  417. 

2  Vol.  v  211-212.  3  R.  v.  Penny  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  153. 

4  Below  364.  s  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  313.  6  Below  407  seqq. 

?R.  v.  Read  (1708)  Fortescue  98;  in  that  case  Powell,  J.,  said,  "this  is  for 
printing  bawdry  stuff,  but  reflects  on  no  person,  and  a  libel  must  be  against  some 
particular  person  or  persons,  or  against  the  Government.  It  is  stuff  not  fit  to  be 
mentioned  publicly;  if  there  should  be  no  remedy  in  the  Spiritual  Court,  it  does  not 
follow  there  must  be  a  remedy  here.  There  is  no  law  to  punish  it,  I  wish  there  were, 
but  we  cannot  make  law." 

8  (1727)  2  Stra.  788 ;  cp.  R.  v.  Hicklin  (1868)  L.R.  3  Q.B.  360. 

9  (1704)  6  Mod.  124.  10  Ibid  at  p.  125.  n  H.C.L.  ii  299-300. 
VOL.  VIII. — 22 


338  CRIME  AND  TORT 

of  the  offence  of  publishing  seditious  writings  or  uttering  seditious 
words,  will  depend  upon  the  view  held  as  to  the  relation  of  rulers 
to  their  subjects.  "  Two  different  views  may  be  taken  of  the 
relation  between  rulers  and  their  subjects.  If  the  ruler  is  regarded 
as  the  superior  of  the  subject,  as  being  by  the  nature  of  his  position 
presumably  wise  and  good  ...  it  must  necessarily  follow  that  it 
is  wrong  to  censure  him  openly,  that  even  if  he  is  mistaken  his 
mistakes  should  be  pointed  out  with  the  utmost  respect,  and  that 
whether  mistaken  or  not,  no  censure  should  be  cast  upon  him 
likely  or  designed  to  diminish  his  authority.  If,  on  the  other 
hand,  the  ruler  is  regarded  as  the  agent  and  servant,  and  the 
subject  as  the  wise  and  good  master,  who  is  obliged  to  delegate 
his  power  to  the  so-called  ruler  ...  it  is  obvious  that  this 
sentiment  must  be  reversed.  Every  member  of  the  public  who 
censures  the  ruler  for  the  time  being  exercises  in  his  own  person 
the  right  which  belongs  to  the  whole  of  which  he  forms  part.  He 
is  finding  fault  with  a  servant.  .  .  .  To  those  who  hold  this  view 
fully,  and  carry  it  out  to  all  its  consequences,  there  can  be  no  such 
offence  as  sedition.  There  may  indeed  be  breaches  of  the  peace 
which  may  destroy  or  endanger  life  limb  or  property,  and  there 
may  be  incitements  to  such  offences.  But  no  imaginable  censure 
of  the  government,  short  of  a  censure  which  has  an  immediate 
tendency  to  produce  such  a  breach  of  the  peace,  ought  to  be 
regarded  as  criminal."  The  first  of  these  two  views  was  the 
accepted  view  in  the  seventeenth  century.  The  second  was 
gathering  strength  during  the  latter  part  of  the  eighteenth  century, 
and  is  now  the  accepted  view.1  It  is  the  history  of  the  develop- 
ment of  the  law  under  the  influence  of  the  first  of  these  views  that 

I  must  here  describe.  The  modifications  effected  by  the  growth 
of  the  second  will  be  dealt  with  in  a  subsequent  Book  of  this 
History. 

We  have  seen  that  both  the  rules  relating  to  the  censorship 
of  the  press,2  and  the  manner  in  which  the  Star  Chamber  ad- 
ministered the  law  of  defamation,3  show  that,  during  this  period, 
the  first  of  these  two  views  was  that  taken  by  the  law.  After 
the  Restoration  the  principles  upon  which  the  Star  Chamber  had 
acted  were  taken  over  by  the  common  law  courts ;  and  it  was 
inevitable  that  this  should  be  so.  We  have  seen  that  statutory 
force  had  been  given  to  a  set  of  rules  for  the  regulation  of  the 
press,  which  were  in  substance  not  dissimilar  to  those  which  had 
been  made  by  the  Star  Chamber.4  The  principles  applied  by 
the  Star  Chamber  to  seditious  writings  had  been  embodied  by 

1  R.  v.  Lovett  (1839)  9  C.  and  P.  at  p.  466  per  Littledale,  J. ;  R.  v.  Suliivan  (1868) 

II  Cox  C.C.  at  p.  58. 

2  Vol.  vi  367-370.  '■'•  Vol.  v  208-212.  4  Vol.  vi  372-3. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  CRIME  339 

Coke  in  the  case  De  Libellis  Famosis ; x  and  he  had  affirmed  that 
these  offences  could  be  punished  either  by  indictment  at  common 
law  or  by  proceedings  in  the  Star  Chamber.2  The  view  held  by 
the  king  and  the  judges  as  to  the  relation  between  rulers  and  their 
subjects,  were  the  same  as  those  held  by  the  king  and  his  judges 
in  the  earlier  part  of  the  century.  Hence  we  find  that  the  judges 
accepted  the  rules  that  truth  was  no  defence  to  an  indictment,3 
that  publication  was  not  necessary,4  and  that  the  death  of  the 
person  libelled  was  not  necessarily  a  bar  to  a  prosecution.5  They 
also  accepted  the  rules  that  the  contriver  the  procurer  and  the 
publisher  were  all  equally  guilty;0  and  Holt,  C.J.  made  it  quite 
clear  that  both  the  writing  and  the  copying  of  a  libel,  without  just 
cause  or  excuse,  amounted  to  the  contriving  of  a  libel.7  Similarly, 
the  common  law  courts  had  shown,  in  the  earlier  part  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  that  they  were  prepared  to  follow  the  lead  of  the 
Star  Chamber,8  and  treat  seditious  words  in  substantially  the 
same  manner  as  seditious  writings.  Part  of  the  charge  against 
Eliot  Holies  and  Valentine  was  the  uttering  of  seditious  words  ;9 
and  other  cases  show  that  the  common  law  courts  treated  as 
criminal  seditious  words  not  only  against  the  king,10  but  also 
against  his  government,11  the  judges,12  or  the  established  church.13 

I  (1606)  5  Co.  Rep.  125a.  2  At  ff.  125a,  125b. 

3  Vol.  v  210  ;  Anon  (1707)  11  Mod.  99  ;  Bl.  Comm.  iv  150. 

4  Vol.  v  210 ;  Bl.  Comm.  iv  150. 

8  Vol.  v  211 ;  R.  v.  Topham  (1791)  4  T.R.  126 ;  cp.  R.  v.  Critchley  (1734)  cited 
ibid  129  note  4  ;  Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  1  cap.  73  §  3. 

*  Lamb's  Case  (161 1)  9  Co.  Rep.  59b  ;  vol.  v.  210. 

7  R.  v.  Beare  (1699)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  417 — "  the  writing  of  a  copy  of  a  libel  is 
the  writing  of  a  libel.  And  if  the  law  were  otherwise  it  might  be  very  dangerous,  for 
then  men  might  take  copies  of  them  with  impunity ;  and  for  the  same  reason  the 
printing  of  them  would  be  no  offence  ;  and  then  farewell  to  all  government." 

8  Vol.  v  211. 

9  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  307. 

10  It  is  clear  from  Pine's  Case  (1629)  Cro.  Car.  117,  126,  that  the  judges  con- 
sidered that  an  offence  had  been  committed,  though  it  was  not  treason,  above  312  ; 
R.  v.  Harrison  (1678)  3  Keble  841. 

II  R.  v.  Harrison  (1678)  3  Keble  841  ;  R.  v.  Frost  (1793)  22  S.T.  at  p.  517  ;  cp. 
R.  v.  Winterbotham  (1792)  22  S.T.  823,  875;  R.  v.  Briellat  (1793)  22  S.T.  909. 
Stephen  points  out,  H.C.L.  ii  377,  that  no  prosecution  for  this  offence  has  taken  place 
for  many  years ;  but  that  "  seditious  language  has  on  several  occasions  been  made  the 
subjtct  of  prosecutions,  the  charge  being  that  of  unlawful  assembly  or  seditious  con- 
spiracy, of  which  violent  speeches  have  been  regarded  as  overt  acts." 

12  justice  Hutton's  Case  (1639)  Hutton  131 ;  R.  v.  Gordon  (1787)  22  S.T.  175  ;  in 
later  law,  when  the  jurisdiction  to  punish  for  contempt  was  extended,  such  libels  could 
be  treated  as  contempts,  and  dealt  with  by  the  summary  process  of  attachment,  vol. 
iii.  394.  Judges  of  inferior  courts  can  only  fine  or  attach  for  contempt  if  the  words 
are  spoken  in  court,  Earl  of  Lincoln  v.  Fysher  ^(1595)  Cro.  Eliza.  581 ;  Bathhurst  v. 
Cox  (1662)  Th.  Raym.  68  ;  for  contemptuous  words  spoken  out  of  court  only  surety 
for  the  peace  can  be  required,  R.  v.  Langley  (1704)  2  Salk.  697. 

13  R.  -v.  Taylor  (1676)  1  Vent.  293  ;  cp.  Atwood's  Case  (1618)  Cro.  Jac.  421 ; 
Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  i  cap.  5  §  6 ;  Atwood's  Case  perhaps  shows  that  the  influence  of 
the  jurisdiction  of  the  court  of  High  Commission  may  have  helped  to  produce  this 
particular  development ;  however  that  may  be,  it  was  quite  in  harmony  with  the 
prevalent  views  to  the  relation  between  Church  and  State,  below  406-410. 


340  CRIME  AND  TORT 

That  this  view  of  the  criminality  of  seditious  words  was  com- 
paratively new  law,  derived  from  the  practice  of  the  Star 
Chamber,  is  probable  from  a  case  of  1558,  in  which  it  was  held 
that  slander  spoken  of  the  queen  was  punishable  under  Edward  I.'s 
statute  of  scandalum  magnatum.1  However  that  may  be,  it  is  clear 
that  the  offence  of  uttering  seditious  words  was  definitely  recog- 
nised to  be  a  misdemeanour,  punishable  by  the  common  law 
courts,  in  the  earlier  part  of  the  seventeenth  century ;  and  it  is 
fairly  clear  that,  as  in  the  case  of  publishing  seditious  writings, 
this  broad  rule  was  derived  from  the  practice  of  the  Star  Chamber. 
It  follows,  therefore,  that  the  offence  was  defined  as  widely  by 
the  common  law  courts  as  by  the  court  of  Star  Chamber.  This 
is  abundantly  clear,  both  from  the  resolutions  of  the  judges,  and 
from  the  numerous  cases  of  seditious  libel  which  came  before  the 
courts  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century.  Thus  in 
1663  it  was  resolved'2  that  "  tho'  printing  be  a  trade,  and  selling 
of  books  also,  they  must  use  their  trade  according  to  law,  and  not 
abuse  it,  by  printing  and  selling  of  books  scandalous  to  the  Govern- 
ment or  tending  to  sedition."  Later  in  the  reign  the  judges  made 
use  of  the  Licensing  Acts 3  to  sharpen  the  edge  of  the  law.  They 
resolved  that  it  was  illegal  to  publish  anything  whatever  without 
authority,  even  though  it  was  not  scandalous  to  the  government. 
It  was  therefore  doubly  illegal  if  that  which  was  published  was 
scandalous.  The  law  was  laid  down  in  this  way  by  Scroggs,  C.J., 
in  R.  v.  Carr?  and  R.  v.  Harris 5  /  and  Stephen  points  out  that, 
though  the  House  of  Commons  impeached  Scroggs  for  many  illegal 
and  arbitrary  acts,  it  did  not  allege  that  this  statement  of  the  law 
was  wrong.6  This  view  of  the  law  was  applied  in  the  case  of 
R.  v.  Barnardiston?  who  was  sentenced  "to  a  monstrous  fine  of 
£1 0,000  for  the  mere  expression  of  political  opinions  to  a  private 
friend  in  a  private  letter  "  ; 8  in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Baxter,9  who  was 
thought  in  his  paraphrase  of  the  New  Testament  to  have  reflected 
upon  the  bishops  of  the  church  of  England ;  in  the  case  of  R.  v. 
Johnson™  who  issued  an  address  to  the  Protestants  in  the  army  not 

1  Oldnoll's  Case,  Dyer  155a ;  for  this  offence  see  vol.  iii  409-410. 

2  Kelyng  23.  3  Vol.  vi  372. 

4  Dealing  with  the  word  "illicite"  in  the  indictment  he  said,  "  I  must  recite 
what  Mr.  Recorder  told  you  of  at  first,  what  all  the  judges  of  England  have  declared 
under  their  hands.  The  words  I  remember  are  these :  When,  by  the  king's  com- 
mand, we  were  to  give  in  our  opinion  what  was  to  be  done  in  point  of  regulation  of 
the  press  ;  we  did  all  subscribe,  that  to  print  or  publish  any  news  books  or  pamphlets 
of  news  whatsoever,  is  illegal ;  that  it  is  a  manifest  intent  to  the  breach  of  the  peace, 
and  they  may  be  proceeded  against  by  law  for  an  illegal  thing.  Suppose  now  that 
this  thing  is  not  scandalous,  what  then  ?  If  there  had  been  no  reflection  in  this  book 
at  all,  yet  it  is  illicite,  and  the  author  ought  to  be  convicted  for  it,"  (1680)  7  S.T.  at 
p.  1127. 

5  (1680)  7  S.T.  at  pp.  929-930.  «  H.C.L.  ii  313.  7  (1684)  9  S.T.  1333. 
8  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  314.     '       "  (1685)  11  S.T.  493.            10(i686)  n  S.T.  1339. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  CRIME  341 

to  assist  Papists  illegally  enlisted  and  commissioned  ;  and  in  the 
case  of  The  Seven  Bisno/>s,1  who  were  put  on  their  trial  for  asserting 
that  the  king's  declaration  of  indulgence  was  illegal,  because  it  was 
based  on  a  prerogative  to  suspend  laws  which  did  not  exist 
These  cases  are  a  few  illustrations,2  and  some  are  very  extreme 
illustrations,  of  the  prevailing  theory  that  a  person  who  questioned 
the  legality  or  the  policy  of  any  act  of  the  government,  even  in  a 
respectful  manner,  committed  the  offence  of  seditious  libel.  The 
law  was  severely  and  brutally  applied,  especially  by  Jeffreys,  but 
it  is  difficult  to  say,  in  the  then  state  of  the  law,  that  these  decisions 
were  wrong.3 

The  expiration  of  the  Licensing  Act  in  1 694 4  made  it  impos- 
sible to  say  that  the  mere  publication  of  a  writing  without  authority 
was  illegal.  But  neither  the  expiration  of  that  Act,  nor  the  Revolu- 
tion, materially  altered  the  law  as  to  what  constituted  a  seditious 
libel.  This  is  clear  from  the  ruling  of  Holt,  C.  J.,  in  R.  v.  Tutchin : 5 
"  they  say  nothing  is  a  libel  but  what  reflects  upon  some  particular 
person.  But  this  is  a  very  strange  doctrine  to  say  it  is  not  a  libel 
reflecting  on  the  government,  endeavouring  to  possess  the  people 
that  the  government  is  maladministered  by  corrupt  persons,  that 
are  employed  in  such  or  such  stations  either  in  the  navy  or  army. 
To  say  that  corrupt  officers  are  appointed  to  administer  affairs  is 
certainly  a  reflection  on  the  government.  If  people  should  not  be 
called  to  account  for  possessing  the  people  with  an  ill  opinion  of  the 
government,  no  government  can  subsist.  For  it  is  very  necessary 
for  all  governments  that  the  people  should  have  a  good  opinion  of 
it  And  nothing  can  be  worse  to  any  government  than  to  en- 
deavour to  procure  animosities  as  to  the  management  of  it ;  this 
has  always  been  looked  upon  as  a  crime,  and  no  government  can 
be  safe  without  it" 

It  would  seem  to  follow  from  this  view  of  the  nature  of 
seditious  libel  that  the  crime  of  seditious  libel  was  the  intentional 
publication  of  a  writing  which  reflected  on  the  government ;  and, 
similarly,  that  the  crime  of  libel  committed  against  a  private  person 
was  the  intentional  publication  of  a  writing  which  held  him  up  to 
hatred  contempt  or  ridicule.  But  when  criminal  proceedings  were 
taken  for  libel,  it  was  always  alleged,  that  the  accused  had  published 
the  libel  with  a  whole  series  of  the  worst  intentions.  He  was  said 
to  have  acted  falsely,  seditiously,  maliciously,  and  factiously.  As 
Stephen  has  said,  "  round  full  mouthed  abuse  of  people  who  gave 

1  (1688)  12  S.T.  183. 

2  "  The  great  frequency  of  prosecutions  for  political  libels  and  seditious  words  at 
this  time  appears  .  .  .  from  a  passage  in  Luttrell's  Diary  for  the  year  1684,  which 
enumerates  sixteen  trials  for  those  offences  between  April  30  and  November  28  in 
that  year,"  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  313. 

3  Ibid  ii  3I3-3I5-  *Vol.  vi  375.  9(i7<H)  *4  S-T.  at  p.  1138. 


342  CRIME  AND  TORT 

offence  to  the  government  was  thought  natural  and  proper "  ;  ! 
and,  as  we  can  see  from  the  indictments  for  other  offences,  and 
even  from  the  declarations  in  civil  actions,  it  was  customary, 
wherever  an  accusation  of  any  sort  of  wrong  was  made,  to  exhibit 
the  defendant's  conduct  in  the  worst  possible  light.  Naturally  the 
use  of  these  common  forms  tended  to  give  rise  to  the  view  that  the 
crime  was,  not  so  much  the  intentional  publication  of  matter  bear- 
ing the  seditious  or  defamatory  meaning  alleged  by  the  prosecution, 
as  its  publication  with  a  seditious  or  malicious  intent.  This  view 
of  the  nature  of  libel  regarded  as  a  criminal  offence  begins  to 
appear  in  the  eighteenth  century  ;  and  it  has  had  a  large  influence 
on  its  history.  We  shall  see  later,  that  it  has  reacted  on  the  views 
held  as  to  the  nature  of  libel  considered  as  a  tort ;  and  that  the 
idea  that  a  malicious  intent  is  a  necessary  ingredient,  both  in  the 
crime  and  in  the  tort  of  defamation,  has  not  been  finally  got  rid  of 
till  the  nineteenth  century.2  The  reasons  for  its  appearance  we 
must  now  consider. 

In  the  earlier  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  when  the  crime 
of  libel,  and  especially  of  seditious  libel,  was  chiefly  dealt  with 
by  the  court  of  Star  Chamber,  the  question  whether  the  offence 
consisted  of  intentionally  publishing  a  seditious  or  a  defamatory 
writing,  or  whether  it  consisted  of  intentionally  publishing  such 
writings  with  a  seditious  or  a  malicious  intent,  was  academic. 
It  was  academic  because  the  court  decided  all  questions  both  of 
fact  and  of  law.  If  the  offence  consisted  of  intentionally  publishing 
a  writing  with  the  seditious  or  defamatory  meaning  alleged  by  the 
prosecution,  it  decided  the  questions  whether  the  writing  had 
been  intentionally  published  and  whether  it  meant  what  the  pro- 
secution alleged  that  it  meant,  which  were  questions  of  fact ;  and 
it  decided  whether  what  was  so  published  was  seditious,  defamatory 
or  otherwise  malicious,  and  so  a  libel,  which  was  a  question  of 
law.  Similarly,  if  the  offence  consisted  of  intentionally  publishing 
such  a  writing  with  a  seditious  or  a  malicious  intent,  it  decided  as 
questions  of  fact  both  whether  such  a  writing  had  been  intentionally 
published  with  this  seditious  or  malicious  intent,  and  whether  it 
meant  what  the  prosecution  alleged  that  it  meant ;  and,  as  a 
question  of  law,  whether  such  a  writing  published  with  that  intent 
was  in  law  a  libel. 

But  when  the  jurisdiction  over  these  libels  was  taken  over  by 
the  courts  of  common  law,  the  question  ceased  to  be  academic. 
The  courts  of  common  law  worked  with  a  jury  ;  and  that  involved 
an  accurate  delimitation  of  the  spheres  of  fact  and  law.  If  the 
essence  of  libel  was  the  publication  with  a  seditious  defamatory  or 
otherwise  malicious  intent,  the  finding  of  that  intent  was  matter  of 

1  H.C.L.  ii  354.  2  Below  373-375. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  CRIME  343 

fact  for  the  jury.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  its  essence  was  the  in- 
tentional publication  of  the  document  set  out  in  the  indictment,  all 
that  the  jury  was  concerned  with  was  the  fact  of  such  publication, 
and  the  question  whether  it  bore  the  seditious  or  defamatory 
meaning  alleged  by  the  prosecution.1  Now  it  is  obvious  that  if  the 
malicious  intent  was  an  essential  ingredient  in  the  offence,  and  if, 
therefore,  this  was  a  question  for  the  jury,  the  jury  would  have  far 
larger  powers  than  if  they  were  required  to  decide  only  the  ques- 
tion of  intentional  publication  of  a  document  with  the  meaning 
alleged  in  the  indictment.  As  all  these  cases  of  seditious  libels 
were  regarded  as  matters  nearly  affecting  the  state,  and  as,  after 
the  decision  in  BushelVs  Case,2  the  control  of  the  government 
over  the  judges 3  was  far  closer  than  its  control  over  juries,  it  is  not 
surprising  that  the  courts  should  have  laid  it  down  that  the  malicious 
intent  was.  not  an  essential  ingredient  in  the  offence,  but  that  the 
offence  consisted  of  the  intentional  publication  of  a  document  with 
the  seditious  or  defamatory  meaning  alleged  by  the  prosecution. 
It  followed  that  the  function  of  the  jury  was  limited  to  finding 
these  two  sets  of  facts ;  and  that  it  was  for  the  court  to  say  as  a 
matter  of  law  whether  a  writing  published  with  this  seditious  or 
defamatory  meaning  was  a  libel. 

Thus  in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Carr*  Scroggs,  C.  J.,  directed  the  jury 
that,  if  they  found  that  the  accused  had  published  the  book,  they  must 
find  him  guilty.  "  If  you  find  him  guilty  and  say  what  he  is 
guilty  of,  we  will  judge  whether  the  thing  imports  malice  or  not. 
Sir  Francis  Winnington  hath  told  you  there  are  some  things  that 
do  necessarily  imply  malice  in  them.  If  this  thing  doth  not  imply 
it,  then  the  judges  will  go  according;  to  sentence,  if  it  doth;0 
so  that  it  concerns  not  you  one  farthing,  whether  malicious  or  not 
malicious — that  is  plain."6  The  same  ruling  was  given,  even 
more  plainly,  in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Barnardiston.  It  was  argued 
that,  as  there  was  no  evidence  of  malice  in  the  publication  of  the 
writing,  the  accused  was  entitled  to  be  acquitted.  To  that  the 
reply  was  given  that  malice  cannot  be  proved  by  direct  evidence; 
but  that,  just  as  a  killing  without  provocation  proved  that  the  killing 
was  with  malice  afore  thought,  so  the  publication  of  a  seditious  writing 
proved  the  malicious  intent  "  In  case  any  person  doth  write 
libels,  or  publish  any  expressions  which  in  themselves  carry 
sedition  and  faction  and  ill  will  towards  the  government,  I  cannot 
tell  well  how  to  express  it  otherwise  in  his  accusation  than  by 
such  words  that  he  did  it  seditiously  factiously  and  maliciously. 
And  the  proof  of  the  thing  itself  proves  the  evil  mind  it  was  done 

1  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  350  seqq.  3  (1670)  Vaughan  135  ;  vol.  i  345-3^- 

3  Vol.  vi  503-511.  *  (1680)  7  S.T.  nil. 

5  The  punctuation  has  been  amended,  '  At  p.  1128, 


344  CRIME  AND  TORT 

with.  If  then,  gentlemen,  you  believe  the  defendant,  Sir  Samuel 
Barnardiston,  did  write  and  publish  these  letters,  that  is  proof 
enough  of  the  words  maliciously,  seditiously  and  factiously  laid  in 
the  information."  1  No  doubt  in  the  Case  of  the  Seven  Bishops  the 
malicious  and  seditious  intent  of  the  writing  was  left  to  the  jury. 
But  we  have  seen  that  in  that  case  all  the  legal  talent  of  the  day 
was  enlisted  on  the  side  of  the  bishops.  The  bar  was  altogether 
too  much  for  a  bench  of  judges  approved  by  James  II.  ;2  so  that, 
as  Stephen  says,  "it  is  impossible  to  appeal  to  that  case  as  a  pre- 
cedent for  any  legal  proposition  whatever."  3,  It  is  true  also  that 
in  the  case  of  R.  v.  Tutchin*  some  expressions  used  by  Holt,  C.J., 
may  be  taken  to  mean  that  the  intention  with  which  the  writing 
was  composed  was  to  be  left  to  the  jury.5  But  probably  Stephen 
and  Lord  Mansfield,  C.J.,  are  right  in  thinking  that  his  words  do 
not  bear  this  construction,  and  that  he  meant  to  lay  down  the  law 
substantially  as  it  had  been  laid  down  in  the  seventeenth  century.6 
At  any  rate  this  was  the  the  sense  in  which  the  law  was  under- 
stood by  Raymond,  C.J.  In  the  case  of  R.  v.  Francklin1  he  said, 
"  in  this  information  for  libel  there  are  three  things  to  be 
considered,  whereof  two  by  you  the  jury,  and  one  by  the  court. 
The  first  thing  under  your  consideration  is  whether  the  defendant 
Mr.  Francklin  is  guilty  of  the  publication  of  this  Craftsman  or  not? 
The  second  is,  whether  the  expressions  in  that  letter  refer  to  his 
present  majesty  and  his  principal  officers  and  ministers  of  state, 
and  are  applicable  to  them  or  not?  .  .  .  But  then  there  is  a 
third  thing,  to  wit,  whether  these  defamatory  expressions  amount 
to  a  libel  or  not  ?  This  does  not  belong  to  the  office  of  the  jury,  but 
to  the  office  of  the  Court ;  because  it  is  a  matter  of  law,  and  not 
of  fact ;  .   .  .  and  there  is  redress  to  be  had  at  another   place  if 

1  (1684)  9  S.T.  at  p.  1352 ;  ibid  at  p.  1349  Jeffreys  said,  "  The  law  supplies  the 
proof  if  the  thing  itself  speaks  malice  and  sedition.  As  it  is  in  murder,  we  say  always 
in  the  indictment,  he  did  it  by  the  instigation  of  the  devil :  can  the  jury  if  they  find 
the  fact,  find  he  did  it  not  by  such  instigation  ?  No,  that  does  necessarily  attend  the 
very  nature  of  such  an  action  or  thing.  So,  in  informations  for  offences  of  this  nature, 
we  say,  he  did  it  falsely  maliciously  and  seditiously,  which  are  the  formal  words ; 
but  if  the  nature  of  the  thing  necessarily  imports  malice  reproach  and  scandal  to  the 
government,  then  needs  no  proof  but  of  the  fact  done,  the  law  supplies  the  rest "  ;  it  was 
for  this  reason,  no  doubt,  that  the  jury  were  directed  that,  if  they  found  the  pub- 
lication of  a  document  with  the  meaning  alleged  by  the  prosecution,  they  were  directed 
to  give  a  general  verdict  of  guilty,  as  to  this  see  below  345  and  n.  1. 

2  Vol.  vi  511. 

3  H.C.L.  ii  315-316 — "  The  question  whether  or  not  the  king  had  a  dispensing 
power  was  clearly  a  question  of  law  and  not  of  fact,  nevertheless  the  records  were 
allowed  to  go  to  the  jury  as  evidence  that  the  law  was  as  the  bishops  said  it  was. 
This  carries  the  powers  of  the  jury  even  further  than  they  would  be  carried  at  the 
present  day."     Stephen  should  have  said  suspending  power. 

4 (1704)  14  S.T.  1095. 

5 "  Now  you  are  to  consider  whether  these  words  I  have  read  to  you  do  not  tend 
to  beget  an  ill  opinion  of  the  administration  of  the  government,"  at  p.  1128. 
6  H.C.L.  ii  317-319.  7  (1731)  17  S.T.  at  pp.  671-672. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  CRIME  345 

either  of  the  parties  are  not  satisfied  ;  for  we  are  not  to  invade  one 
another's  province,  as  is  now  of  late  a  notion  among  some  people 
who  ought  to  know  better." 

Down  to  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century,  therefore, 
the  essence  of  a  libel  was  the  intentional  publication  of  a  docu- 
ment, bearing  the  seditious  or  defamatory  meaning  alleged  by  the 
prosecution.  It  followed  that  all  the  jury  had  to  do  was  to  find 
the  fact  of  publication  of  a  document  bearing  the  meaning  alleged 
by  the  prosecution;  and  that  it  was  for  the  court  to  say,  as  a 
matter  of  law,  whether  what  was  published  was  seditious, 
defamatory,  or  otherwise  malicious,  and  so  a  libel.  This  state  of 
the  law  harmonised  admirably  with  the  current  views  as  to  the 
relations  of  rulers  to  their  subjects.  But,  when  those  views 
changed,  it  gradually  came  to  be  wholly  out  of  touch  with  current 
public  opinion.  The  law  as  to  what  amounted  to  a  seditious 
libel,  having  been  formed  in  the  period  when  the  ruler  was 
regarded  as  the  superior  of  his  subjects,  assorted  badly  with  the 
new  view  that  he  was  their  agent  or  servant  Therefore  the 
desire  for  greater  freedom  of  speech  than  the  existing  law  allowed, 
took  the  technical  form  of  the  contention  that  the  seditious, 
defamatory  or  otherwise  malicious  intention  with  which  a  libel 
was  published,  was  the  essence  of  the  offence,  and  so  a  matter  of 
fact  for  the  jury.  In  support  of  this  contention  much  was  made 
of  the  fact  that  the  jury  were  told  to  find  a  general  verdict  of 
guilty,  when,  according  to  the  then  received  view  of  the  nature  of 
a  libel,  their  finding  amounted  merely  to  a  special  verdict  that  a 
certain  writing  with  a  certain  meaning  had  been  published  by  the 
accused,  which  might  be  ruled  to  be  perfectly  innocent.1  The 
concluding  sentence  from  the  passage  in  Raymond,  C.J.'s,  summing 
up  in  R.  v.  Francklin  cited  above,  shows  that  at  that  date  this 
contention  was  beginning  to  be  advanced.  The  eloquence  and 
ability  with  which  Erskine  advocated  it  later  in  the  century,  pro- 
duced a  statutory  change  in  the  law,2  which  has  had  great  effects 
on  the  law  of  libel  whether  considered  as  a  crime  or  as  a  tort.3 
But  these  developments  and  their  effects  upon  the  modern  law 
belong,  as  I  have  said,  to  the  legal  history  of  the  eighteenth 
century. 

1  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  358 — "They  (the  judges)  tried  to  make  the  verdict  of 
guilty  in  trials  for  libel  an  imperfect  special  verdict,  which  would  have  the  effect  of 
convicting  the  defendant,  even  if  he  was  innocent  in  the  opinion  of  the  judge  who  tried 
him,  subject  to  his  getting  the  court  to  quash  his  conviction  upon  a  motion  in  arrest  of 
judgment "  ;  note  that  in  R.  v.  Harris  (1680)  7  S.T.  at  p.  931,  Scroggs,  C.  J.,  refused 
to  accept  a  verdict  of  guilty  of  selling  only,  compelled  the  jury  to  give  a  general 
verdict  of  guilty,  and  then  reprimanded  them  for  trying  to  qualify  their  verdict  con- 
trary to  the  direction  of  the  Court. 

-  32  George  III.  c.  60  (Fox's  Libel  Act) ;  below  374. 

3  Stephen,  H.C.L,  ii  321  seqq. 


346  CRIME  AND  TORT 

On  other  questions  connected  with  libel  considered  as  a  crime 
there  is  as  yet  but  little  authority.  We  hear  little,  for  instance, 
of  the  defence  of  privilege.  That  is  a  topic  which  will,  as  we 
shall  see,1  be  developed  mainly  in  connection  with  defamation  con- 
sidered as  a  tort.  Similarly,  though  it  was  quite  clear  that  the 
words  or  writing  complained  of  must  be  set  out  in  the  indictment 
or  information,  together  with  any  innuendoes  necessary  to  explain 
their  meaning,  it  was  chiefly  in  connection  with  the  tort  that  the 
learning  as  to  the  function  of  the  innuendo  was  developed.2  On 
both  these  matters  rules  were  evolved  which  were  later  applied  to 
some  or  all  forms  of  the  criminal  offence.  On  the  other  hand, 
some  of  the  rules  evolved  in  the  criminal  cases  have  had  an 
equally  great  influence  on  the  development  of  the  tort.  But  the 
reciprocal  influence  of  defamation  regarded  as  a  crime,  and 
defamation  regarded  as  a  tort,  we  shall  be  better  able  to  appreciate 
when  we  have  examined  the  history  of  this  latter  aspect. 

Defamation  as  a  Tort 

Two  sets  of  influences  have  gone  to  the  making  of  our  modern 
torts  of  written  defamation  (libel),  and  spoken  defamation  (slander). 
Firstly,  the  rules  evolved  by  the  working  of  the  common  law 
action  on  the  case  for  defamatory  words  and  writings ;  and 
secondly,  the  rules  applied  by  the  judges,  after  the  Restoration,  to 
written  as  distinct  from  spoken  defamation.  To  the  first  of  these 
influences  we  can  trace  a  large  number  of  the  principal  rules 
common  to  both  libel  and  slander :  to  the  second,  the  original 
elaboration  of  the  unfortunate  distinction  between  these  two 
closely  allied  torts.  In  tracing  their  history  I  shall  deal  with  (i) 
the  early  history  of  the  common  law  action  for  defamation  ;  (2)  the 
origin  of  the  difference  between  libel  and  slander ;  and  (3)  the 
origin  of  some  of  the  essential  characteristics  of  the  torts  of  libel 
and  slander. 

(1)  The  early  history  of  the  common  law  action  for  defama- 
tion. 

I  shall  consider  this  subject  under  the  two  following  heads  : — 
(i)  the  nature  and  scope  of  the  action ;  and  (ii)  the  methods  used 
by  the  common  law  judges  in  the  seventeenth  century  to  dis- 
courage this  action,  and  their  effects. 

(i)    The  nature  and  scope  of  the  action. 

Of  this  I  have  already  said  something.  We  have  seen  that, 
because  the  action  was  an  action  on  the  case,  the  damage  not  the 

1  Below  375-377.  9  Below  368-369. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  347 

insult  was  its  gist ;  and  that  it  followed  from  this  conception  of 
the  action,  that,  firstly,  publication  to  some  third  person  was  essen- 
tial, that,  secondly,  truth  was  a  defence  to  the  action,  and  that, 
thirdly,  like  other  actions  for  tort,  it  died  with  the  person.1  We 
have  seen,  too,  that  the  action  was  applicable  both  to  written  and 
spoken  defamation.2  We  shall  see  that  it  was  not  till  after  the 
Restoration,  and  under  the  influence  of  ideas  derived  from  the 
criminal  offence  of  libel,  that  the  modern  distinction  between 
libel  and  slander  was  introduced.3 

The  nature  of  the  action,  which  made  it  necessary  to  regard 
the  resulting  damage  rather  than  the  insult  as  the  cause  of  action, 
was,  as  we  have  seen,4  a  cause  which  helped  to  prevent  the 
common  law  from  reaching  an  adequate  conception  of  the  tort  of 
defamation.  But  it  was  not  the  only  cause.  If  the  courts  had 
placed  a  liberal  interpretation  upon  the  character  of  the  reflections 
which  they  would  account  as  defamatory,  and  had  taken  a 
rational  view  as  to  the  kind  of  damage  which  could  be  regarded 
as  the  natural  and  probable  result  of  defamatory  words  or  writings, 
the  law  might  have  been  placed  upon  a  satisfactory  basis.  This 
fact  will,  I  think,  be  made  clear  by  the  development  of  the  rules 
as  to  the  kinds  of  defamation  from  which  damage  could  be  pre- 
sumed— that  is,  to  use  the  modern  expression,  as  to  the  words 
which  are  actionable  per  se ;  by  the  rule  that  words  or  writings, 
though  not  actionable  per  se,  were  actionable  if  they  caused 
damage  ;  and  by  the  development  of  the  tort  of  slander  of  title 
and  torts  analogous  thereto. 

The  rules  as  to  the  kinds  of  defamation  which  are  actionable 
per  se. 

In  the  developed  common  law  words  are  actionable  per  se  if 
they  impute  the  commission  of  a  criminal  offence  punishable  by 
imprisonment,  or  a  contagious  disease  which  would  exclude  a 
person  from  society,  or  unfitness  for  a  profession  trade  or  calling, 
or  misconduct  in  an  office  of  profit  which  would  lead  to  dismissal.5 
It  is  clear  from  March's  book  that  these  categories  had  been 
substantially  reached  by  1647.6 

The  first  of  these  categories  is  probably  the  oldest.      It  dates 

1  Vol.  v  206-207.  2  Ibid  207. 

3  Below  364-365.  *  Above  335. 

5  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  238  ;  Clerk  and  Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  555  ;  Hals- 
bury,  Laws  of  England  xviii  607-608. 

6  "  That  all  scandalous  words  which  touch  or  concern  a  man  in  his  life  liberty  or 
member,  or  any  corporal  punishment ;  or  which  scandal  a  man  in  his  office  or  place 
of  trust ;  or  in  his  calling  or  function  by  which  he  gains  his  living  ;  or  which  tend  to 
the  slandering  of  his  title  or  his  disinheritance ;  or  to  the  loss  of  his  advancement  or 
preferment,  or  any  other  particular  damage ;  or  lastly  which  charge  a  man  to  have 
any  dangerous  infectious  disease  by  reason  of  which  he  ought  to  separate  himself,  or 
to  be  separated  by  the  law,  from  the  society  of  men,"  Actions  for  Slaunder  10-11, 


348  CRIME  AND  TORT 

from  the  period  when  the  action  on  the  case  for  words  was  being 
admitted  into  the  common  law ;  and  it  seems  to  have  originated 
in  the  days  when  the  courts  were  trying  to  distinguish  the 
defamatory  words  which  would  be  actionable  in  the  common  law 
courts,  from  those  which  were  actionable  only  in  the  ecclesiastical 
courts.  The  test  hit  upon  was  contained  in  the  question  whether 
the  offence  charged  was  punishable  in  the  common  law  courts  or 
in  the  ecclesiastical  courts.  If  one  called  another  thief  or  traitor, 
the  offence  charged  was  punishable  in  the  common  law  courts, 
and  therefore  an  action  for  such  defamation  lay  in  those  courts. 
If,  on  the  other  hand,  one  called  another  "  heretic  and  one  of  the 
new  learning,"  or  adulterer,  the  offence  charged  was  "  merely 
spiritual,"  and  no  action  lay  at  common  law.  But  if  the  offence 
charged  was  punishable  by  both  laws,  the  plaintiff  could  bring  his 
action  in  either  jurisdiction.1  This  case  presupposes  that  words 
imputing  a  criminal  offence  are  actionable ;  and  it  seems  to  me 
that,  though  the  court  was  then  merely  trying  to  distinguish 
spheres  of  jurisdiction,  and  not  the  qualities  which  would  make 
words  actionable  per  se,  it  was  probably  the  foundation  of  the 
long  line  of  cases  which  decided  that  such  words  were  thus 
actionable.  Conversely,  it  was  the  origin  of  the  rule  that  words 
imputing  gross  acts  of  immorality  were  not  thus  actionable,  because 
such  acts  were  only  cognizable  by  the  ecclesiastical  courts — an 
injustice  2  which  has  only  partially  been  remedied  by  the  Slander 
of  Women  Act  of  1891.3 

The  other  categories  seem  to  have  been  developed  later,  and 
are  probably  based  upon  the  obvious  tendency  of  the  imputation 
to  cause  damage.  The  imputation  of  a  contagious  disease  seems 
to  have  been  confined  to  statements  that  the  person  defamed  was 

1  Y.B.  27  Hy.  VIII.  Mich.  pi.  4 — see  the  passage  cited  vol.  iii  411  n.  2.  The 
principle  can,  as  is  pointed  out  in  American  Law  Rev.  vi  593,  be  traced  back  to  the 
rule,  which  is  as  old  as  Bracton,  that  the  accessorium  must  come  under  the  same 
jurisdiction  as  the  principale,  see  a  summary  of  this  argument  in  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii 
460  n.  ;  it  should  be  noted  that  the  modern  rule  that  the  criminal  offence  imputed 
must  be  one  punishable  corporally  and  not  merely  by  fine  (see  Webb  v.  Beavan  (1883) 
11  Q.B.D.  609)  is  of  later  growth  ;  no  such  distinction  is  drawn  in  the  Y.B. — indeed  it 
is  not  really  consistent  with  the  principle  there  laid  down  ;  and  apparently  it  was  held, 
in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries,  that  the  mere  fact  that  the  offence 
charged  was  enquirable  in  the  Leet  was  sufficient  to  make  it  actionable  per  se,  Rolle, 
Ab.  i  44  Action  sitr  Case  H.  pi.  8;  but  in  1642  Bramston,  C.J.,  and  Mallet,  J., 
Heath,  J  ,  dissenting,  laid  down  the  modern  rule,  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  59  ;  the 
reason  assigned  for  this  limitation  was  that  if  the  law  were  otherwise,  "  it  would  be  a 
great  occasion  to  increase  and  multiply  actions  for  words." 

2  "  He  (Lord  Campbell)  laments  the  unsatisfactory  state  of  our  law  according  to 
which  the  imputation  of  words,  however  gross,  on  an  occasion  however  public,  upon 
the  chastity  of  a  modest  matron  or  a  pure  virgin,  is  not  actionable  without  proof  that 
it  has  actually  produced  special  temporal  damage  to  her.  The  only  difference  of 
opinion  which  I  have  with  my  noble  and  learned  friend  is  that  instead  of  the  word 
'  unsatisfactory,'  I  should  substitute  the  word  '  barbarous,'  "  Lynch  v.  Knight  (1861) 
9  H.L.C.  at  p.  594  per  Lord  Brougham, 

3  54.  55  Victoria  c.  51. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  349 

suffering  from  leprosy,  the  plague,1  or  syphilis — the  accusation  of 
having  contracted  the  last  mentioned  disease  being  much  the  most 
common  in  the  reports.  It  has  been  suggested  that  the  in- 
clusion in  this  category  of  the  first  two  diseases,  may  have 
originated  in  the  old  rules  which  required  the  removal  of  a  leper 
or  a  person  suffering  from  the  plague.2  Whether  this  be  so  or 
not,  it  is  clear  that  the  imputation  of  having  contracted  syphilis 
was  actionable,  partly  by  reason  of  the  nature  of  the  disease,  and 
partly  by  reason  of  the  obvious  inference  as  to  the  sufferer's  moral 
character.3  Imputation  of  unfitness  for  a  profession  trade  or 
calling  is  obviously  calculated  to  cause  temporal  loss.  There  are 
long  lists  of  cases  in  the  reports  of  the  sort  of  opprobrious  words 
which,  if  used  of  clergymen,4  attorneys,5  barristers,6  justices  of  the 
peace,7  stewards  of  courts,8  doctors,9  traders,10  and  artificers,11  were 
actionable  per  se.  On  these  only  two  remarks  need  be  made. 
Firstly,  it  was  very  early  held  that  the  imputation  that  a  trader 
was  insolvent  or  bankrupt  was  actionable ; 12  and  this  perhaps 
illustrates  the  larger  importance  which  commercial  considerations 
were  assuming.  Secondly,  it  must  be  a  definite  calling  recognized 
by  the  law,  and  not  merely  a  temporary  employment,  or  an 
employment  of  a  menial  nature,  such  as  a  carrier  of  post  letters 13 
— a  limitation  in  which  we  can  perhaps  trace  the  mediaeval  idea 
of  the  distinctness  of  the  status  of  persons  professing  different 
callings.14  An  imputation  of  misconduct  in  an  office  of  profit, 
which  would  lead  to  dismissal,  is  obviously  an  imputation  closely 

1  Though  there  is  one  case  turning  en  an  imputation  of  leprosy  (next  note)  there 
seems  to  be  none  turning  on  an  imputation  of  the  plague  ;  and  though  March,  Actions 
for  Slaunder  105,  thinks  that  such  an  imputation  would  be  actionable,  he  cites  no 
authority 

2  This  suggestion  was  made  in  an  article  in  the  American  Law  Rev.  vi  593  ;  for  a 
summary  of  the  argument  see  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  461 ;  but  it  may  be  doubted 
whether  the  mediaeval  rules  had  much  influence  on  the  minds  of  the  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth-century  judges ;  though  there  is  one  case  turning  on  the  imputation  of 
leprosy,  Taylor  v.  Perkins  (1607)  Cro.  Jac.  144,  the  reason  assigned  for  holding  the 
words  actionable  is  that  such  a  disease  renders  the  sufferer  unfit  for  society,  Rolle,  Ab. 
i  44  pi.  4 ;  but  this  reason  was  not  applied  to  other  infectious  diseases,  e.g.  smallpox, 
see  James  v.  Rutlech  (1599)  4  Co.  Rep.  17a. 

3  "  Si  home  dit  al  auter  que  il  ad  le  grand  Poxe,  action  sur  le  case  gist,  pur  ceo 
que  ceo  est  un  grand  slander  et  disgrace  entant  que  ceo  vient  per  fornication,  et  nul 
home  poet  converser  ove  luy,"  Rolle,  Ab.  i  43,  H.  pi.  3  ;  though  in  another  case  there 
cited,  Crittal  v.  Horner  (1619)  Hob.  219,  it  was  said  that  "  the  slander  was  not  in  the 
wicked  means  of  getting  the  disease,  but  in  the  odiousness  of  the  infection  as  a  leper." 

4  Doctor  Sibthorp's  Case  (1636)  W.  Jones  366. 

5  Rolle,  Ab.  i  52-54,  S.  pi.  1-3,  4-9.  «  Ibid  54_55>  s   pl   l4)  l6?  22 
7  Ibid  57,  S.  pi.  31-34.                              s  ibid  56>  s  pl  2g_ 

9  Ibid  54,  S.  pl.  10-12.  10  Ibid  58-63. 

11  Ibid  62,  V.  pl.  27.  12  Ibid  61,  V.  pl.  16,  citing  a  case  of  1597. 

13  Bell  v.  Thatcher  (1675)  1  Vent.  275— a  doctrine  now  obsolete  as  far  as  applic- 
able to  the  menial  character  of  the  calling,  and  perhaps  also  so  far  as  applicable  to  its 
temporary  character,  see  Clerk  and  Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  557-558  and  the  cases 
there  cited. 

14  Vol.  iii  385-386  ;  vol.  iv  402-407. 


850  CRIME  AND  TORT 

analogous  to  those  just  discussed.  On  this  ground  it  was  said 
that,  "  if  I  have  a  bailiff,  to  whom  I  commit  the  buying  and  selling 
of  my  corn  and  grain,  and  give  him  greater  wages  in  respect  of 
that  trust  and  employment,  and  then  a  man  will  charge  him  to 
have  deceived  me  in  his  office  by  buying  and  selling  by  false 
measure,  to  my  loss  and  damage,  this  will  bear  an  action,  for  this 
discredits  him  in  his  means  of  living :  and  this  kind  of  offence  may 
not  only  be  cause  to  put  him  out  of  that  service  but  to  be  refused 
of  all  others."  *  On  the  same  ground  it  was  held  that  a  charge  of 
unchastity  made  against  a  duke's  chaplain,  whereby  he  lost  his 
office,  was  actionable."  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  office  was  an 
honorary  office,  such  as  a  justice  of  the  peace,  though  a  charge  of 
corruption,  or  of  opinions  showing  that  he  ought  not  to  be  trusted, 
is  actionable,  a  charge  of  want  only  of  ability  is  not. 

The  last  mentioned  case  savours  somewhat  of  the  fine  distinc- 
tions introduced  by  the  judges  who  wished  to  discourage  this  action. 
But  it  is  clear  that  the  broad  principles,  upon  which  the  courts 
adjudged  imputations  to  be  actionable  per  se,  were  not  in  themselves 
unreasonable.  If  they  had  been  supplemented  by  a  somewhat 
greater  latitude  in  allowing  actions  where  damage  could  be  proved, 
the  law  thus  developed  would  not  have  been  wholly  unsatisfactory. 

The  rule  that  words  or  writings,  though  not  actionable  per  se, 
were  actionable  if  they  caused  damage. 

Though  the  words  spoken  amounted  to  a  slander  punishable 
only  in  the  ecclesiastical  courts,  yet  if  it  could  be  proved  that 
temporal  loss  had  been  occasioned  by  them,  an  action  lay.  Thus, 
if  one  accused  a  woman  of  incontinency,  whereby  she  lost  a 
marriage  which  was  being  arranged,  she  had  a  right  of  action. 
"  For  in  this  case  the  ground  of  the  action  is  temporal,  sc.  that  she 
was  to  be  advanced  in  marriage,  and  that  she  was  defeated  of  it, 
and  the  means  by  which  she  was  defeated  was  the  same  slander, 
which  means  tending  to  such  end,  shall  be  tried  by  the  common 
law.  So  if  a  divine  is  to  be  presented  to  a  benefice,  and  one  to 
defeat  him  of  it  says  to  the  patron  'that  he  is  an  heretic,  or  a 
bastard,  or  that  he  is  excommunicated,'  by  which  the  patron  re- 
fuses to  present  him  .  .  .  and  he  loses  his  preferment,  he  shall 
have  his  action  on  the  case  for  these  slanders  tending  to  such  end. 
.  .  .  And  Popham  Chief  Justice  said  that  if  one  says  of  a  woman 
that  keeps  an  inn  that  she  has  a  great  infectious  disease  by  which 

1  Bray  v.  Hayne  (1615)  Hob.  76. 

2  Payne  v.  Beuwmorris  (1668)  1  Lev.  248 ;  cp.  Gallway  v.  Marshall  (1853) 
9  Exch.  294. 

3  How  v.  Prinn  (1702)  2  Salk.  at  p.  695 — in  that  case  it  was  held  actionable  to 
say  of  a  justice  of  the  peace  and  a  deputy  lieutenant  that  he  was  a  Jacobite,  and  for 
bringing  in  the  Prince  of  Wales  and  popery  to  destroy  our  nation  ;  cp.  Alexander  v. 
Jenkins  [1892]  1  Q.B.  797  ;  Booth  v.  Arnold  [1895]  1  Q.B.  571. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  351 

she  loses  her  guests,  she  shall  have  an  action  on  the  case."  '  Simi- 
larly, if  it  was  affirmed  that  a  person  was  a  bastard,  whereby  his 
title  or  possibility  of  a  title  to  land  was  negatived,  and  he  lost  a 
chance  of  selling  his  title  or  possibility  of  title,  he  had  a  right  of 
action.2  This  last  illustration  comes  very  near  to  slander  of  title 
which,  as  we  shall  now  see,  became  a  separate  tort  in  the  course 
of  the  seventeenth  century. 

The  development  of  the  tort  of  slander  of  title  and  torts  analogous 
thereto. 

Cases  of  the  latter  part  of  the  sixteenth  century  established 
the  principle  that,  if  an  owner  of  land  was  negotiating  for  its  sale 
or  other  disposition  to  another  person,  and  a  third  person  made 
false  statements  as  to  the  vendor's  title,  which  prevented  the  sale 
or  disposition,  the  vendor  could  bring  an  action  on  the  case  and 
get  damages  for  the  slander.3  This  action  on  the  case  is  clearly 
analogous  to  the  ordinary  action  on  the  case  for  defamation ;  and 
in  the  fact  that  it  makes  no  difference  whether  the  slander  is  oral 
or  written,4  it  preserves  the  memory  of  a  characteristic  which  this 
ordinary  action  then  possessed.5  Both  sprang  from  the  same  root ; 
but,  from  an  early  period,  differences  between  the  conditions  under 
which  the  action  for  slander  of  title  and  the  ordinary  action  lay 
began  to  be  developed.  The  action  for  slander  of  title  did  not  lie 
if  the  third  person  claimed  that  he  was  entitled,  though  his  claim 
were  false ; 6  and  the  statement  must  be  made  with  knowledge  of 
its  falsity.7  As  early  as  1629  it  was  recognized  that  the  form  and 
incidents  of  the  action  were  different  from  those  of  the  ordinary 
action  for  defamation 8 — though  it  was  probably  not  till  the  latter 
half  of  the  century  that  these  differences  were  universally  recog- 
nized.9    In  substance  it  was  an  action  for  malicious  statements  as  to 

1  Davis  v.  Gardiner  (1593)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  17a;  Mathew  v.  Crass  (1614)  Cro. 
Jac.  323. 

8  Vaughan  v.  Ellis  (1609)  Cro.  Jac.  213 ;  Elborow  v.  Allen  (1623)  ibid  642. 

3  Mildmay  v.  Standish  (1585)  Cro.  Eliza.  34  ;  Gerrard  v.  Dickenson  (1591)  ibid  196  ; 
Tasburgh  v.  Day  (1619)  Cro.  Jac.  484 ;  that  it  should  hinder  a  pending  sale  was 
essential,  see  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  91,  citing  a  dictum  of  Popham. 

4  Ratcliffe  v.  Evans  [1892]  2  Q.B.  at  p.  527  per  Bowen,  L.J. 

5  Above  347  ;  vol.  v  207 ;  below  364. 

6  "  If  the  defendant  had  affirmed  and  published  that  the  plaintiff  had  no  right  to 
the  castle  and  manor  of  H,  but  that  the  herself  had  right  to  them,  in  that  case,  because 
the  defendant  herself  pretends  right  to  them,  although  in  truth  she  had  none,  yet  no 
action  lies,"  Gerrard  v.  Dickenson  (1585)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  iSa. 

7  Ibid  at  f.  18b. 

8,1  The  action  is  out  of  the  statute  21  Jac.  I.  c.  16  as  well  for  the  time  of  limitation 
as  for  the  costs,  for  that  extends  to  actions  for  slanderous  words  which  are  intended 
to  the  persons  of  men,  and  are  common  actions,  and  rather  begin  of  spleen  than 
otherwise ;  but  not  to  this  action,  which  is  rare,  and  not  brought  without  special 
damage,"  Law  v.  Harwood  (1629)  Cro.  Car.  at  p.  141. 

9  That  the  differentiation  was  not  always  clearly  perceived  in  the  earlier  half  of 
the  seventeenth  century  is  clear  from  the  passage  from  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder 
10-11,  cited  above  347  n.  6  ;  in  fact  the  rule  laid  down  in  Law  v.  Harwood  as  to  the 
application  of  the  statute  applied  to  any  action  on  the  case  for  words,  in  which  special 


352  CRIME  AND  TORT 

the  title  to  property,  oral  or  written,  made  with  knowledge  of  their 
falsity,  which  had  caused  damage  to  the  plaintiff.1  In  the  seven- 
teenth century  the  action  was  extended  to  other  cases  in  which 
damage  had  been  thus  caused.  Thus  in  1662,  in  the  case  of 
Sheperd  v.  Wakeman?  it  was  held,  after  much  debate,  that  a  state- 
ment made  falsely  and  maliciously  of  a  plaintiff,  whereby  she  lost 
a  marriage  for  which  she  was  in  treaty,  was  actionable ;  and  this 
extension  is  the  origin  of  the  general  rule  that  a  tort  is  committed, 
if  damage  is  caused  by  the  making  of  oral  or  written  statements 
falsely  and  maliciously.3  The  action  given  for  this  tort  "  is  not," 
said  Bowen,  L.J.,4  "  one  of  libel  or  of  slander,  but  an  action  on  the 
case  for  damage  wilfully  and  intentionally  done  without  just 
occasion  or  excuse,  analogous  to  an  action  for  slander  of  title." 
This  sentence  not  only  accurately  describes  the  nature  of  the 
action,  but  also  indicates  the  manner  in  which  it  had  been  de- 
veloped. It  is  not  an  action  for  libel  or  slander  for,  historically, 
the  action  for  slander  of  title  and  the  action  on  the  case  for  defama- 
tion became  distinct  at  a  comparatively  early  date ;  and  this  action 
is  simply  an  extension  of  the  action  for  slander  of  title. 

All  these  rules  seem  to  me  to  show  that  there  were  possibilities 
in  this  common  law  action  on  the  case  for  defamation,  which  might 
have  been  developed.  The  different  categories  of  the  sorts  of 
defamation  actionable  per  se  were  both  wide  and  sensible.  The 
rule  that  any  other  kind  of  defamation  causing  temporal  loss  was 
actionable  might,  if  liberally  construed,  have  been  made  to  cover 
other  kinds  of  loss  besides  mere  pecuniary  loss  ;  and  occasionally 
some  of  the  judges  seemed  inclined  to  adopt  this  more  liberal  view.s 
The  development  of  the  tort  of  slander  of  title  and  torts  analogous 
thereto,  showed  that  this  common  law  action  on  the  case  was  a 
vigorous  root,  which  was  capable  of  putting  forth  various  branches. 

damage  was  alleged  (Browne  v.  Gibbons  (1702)  1  Salk.  206),  so  lhat  the  criterion  there 
laid  down  was  not  wholly  conclusive,  which  may  account  for  the  fact  that  it  was 
not  recognized  by  March  as  an  independent  cause  of  action. 

1  Law  v.  Harwood  (1629)  Cro.  Car.  at  p.  141 — "  slandering  of  one's  title  doth 
not  import  in  itself  loss,  without  showing  particularly  the  cause  of  loss  by  reason  of 
the  speaking  of  the  words,  as  that  he  could  not  sell  or  let  the  said  lands  "  ;  and  see 
above  351  n.  6. 

2  (1662)  1  Sid.  79. 

3  Clerk  and  Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  chap,  xviii. 

4  Ratcliffe  v.  Evans  [1892]  2  Q.B.  at  pp.  527-528.  For  another  line  of  cases  where 
damage  is  caused  by  words  spoken  to  the  plaintiff,  which,  therefore,  is  analogous 
neither  to  slander  nor  to  slander  of  title,  see  Wilkinson  v.  Downton  [1897]  2  Q-B. 
57;  Janvier  v.  Sweeney  [19  9]  2  K.B.  316. 

6  "  Williams,  Justice.  This  rule  is  to  be  observed,  as  touching  words  which  are 
actionable,  that  is  to  say,  where  the  words  spoken  do  tend  to  the  infamy,  discredit, 
or  disgrace  of  the  party,  there  the  words  shall  be  actionable,  and  this  rule  was  affirmed 
by  the  Court,"  Smale  v.  Hammon  (1611)  1  Buls.  40;  "And  Holt,  Chief  Justice,  said 
.  .  .  that  for  his  part,  wherever  words  tended  to  take  away  a  man's  reputation  he 
would  encourage  actions  for  them,  because  so  doing  would  contribute  much  to  the 
preservation  of  the  peace,"  Baker  v.  Pierce  (1704)  6  Mod.  at  p.  24. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  353 

But,  as  we  shall  now  see,  these  possibilities  were  never  realized, 
owing  to  the  methods  used  by  the  common  law  judges  in  the 
seventeenth  century  to  discourage  this  action. 

(ii)  The  methods  used  by  the  common  law  judges  in  the  seven- 
teenth century  to  discourage  this  action,  and  their  effects. 

We  have  seen  that,  at  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth  century, 
the  flood  of  these  actions  of  defamation  was  so  overwhelming  that 
the  judges  thought  it  necessary  to  do  all  that  they  could  to  dis- 
courage them.1  The  reasons  why  the  action  was  so  popular  are 
fairly  obvious.  In  the  first  place,  the  Star  Chamber  was  doing  all 
that  it  could  to  suppress  duelling,2  and  therefore  those  who  thought 
that  their  honour  had  been  stained  were  driven  to  the  law  courts. 
In  the  second  place,  we  have  seen  that  litigation  of  all  kinds  is 
always  encouraged  when,  in  a  naturally  turbulent  age,  the  law 
courts  are  sufficiently  strong,  and  the  law  which  they  administer 
is  sufficiently  developed,  to  provide  a  remedy  for  real  or  fancied 
wrongs.3  No  doubt  some  cautious  discouragement  of  these  actions 
was  needed ;  but  the  methods  of  discouragement  devised  by  the 
common  law  judges,  being  somewhat  hasty  and  ill  advised,  did 
permanent  harm  to  the  development  of  this  common  law  action, 
and  therefore  to  the  development  of  the  tort  of  defamation.  These 
methods  of  discouragement  can  be  grouped  under  two  main  heads. 

(a)  A  very  restrictive  interpretation  was  placed  on  the  categories 
of  words  which  the  courts  allowed  to  be  defamatory  per  se ;  and 

(b)  equally  restrictive  rules  were  laid  down  as  to  the  persons  liable 
for  the  repetition  of  a  slander,  as  to  the  kinds  of  damage  for  which 
the  action  lay,  and  as  to  the  kinds  of  damage  which  the  courts 
allowed  to  be  the  natural  and  probable  consequence  of  the 
defamation. 

(a)  Let  us  take  one  or  two  instances  of  the  restrictive  inter- 
pretation placed  on  the  categories  of  words  which  the  courts 
allowed  to  be  defamatory  per  se. 

In  the  case  of  words  which  imported  the  commission  of  a 
criminal  offence  punishable  by  imprisonment,  the  words  were 
strictly  construed  to  see  if  they  charged  the  plaintiff  with  acts 
which  legally  amounted  to  such  an  offence.  Thus,  if  A  said 
of  B,   "  B  seeks  my  life,"  the  words  were  not  actionable,  firstly 

1  Vol.  v  206  ;  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  at  pp.  2-3,  writing  in  1647,  represents 
the  current  professional  opinion  when,  after  remarking  on  the  frequency  of  these 
actions,  he  says,  "  and  it  were  to  be  wished  .  .  .  that  the  greatest  part  of  them  were 
suppressed,  that  words  only  of  brangle  heat  and  choler  might  not  be  so  much  as 
mentioned  in  those  high  and  honourable  courts  of  justice.  For  I  profess  for  my  part 
that  I  judge  of  them  as  a  great  dishonour  to  the  law,  and  the  professors  thereof; 
especially  when  I  consider  that  they  are  used  only  as  instruments  to  promote  the 
malices  and  vent  the  spleen  of  private  jars  and  discontents  among  men." 

2  Ibid  199-201.  3  Vol.  i  506  and  n.  6. 

VOL.  VIII.— 23 


354  CRIME  AND  TORT 

because,  "he  may  seek  his  life  lawfully  upon  just  cause,"  and 
secondly,  "seeking  of  his  life  is  too  general  and  for  seeking 
tantum  no  punishment  is  inflicted  by  the  law."1  To  say  that 
a  man  was  detected  for  perjury  in  the  Star  Chamber  was  not 
actionable,  "  for  an  honest  man  may  be  detected  but  not  con- 
victed ;  and  every  one  who  has  a  bill  of  perjury  exhibited  against 
him  there  is  detected." 2  To  accuse  a  man  of  having  burnt  a  barn 
was  held  not  to  be  actionable,  as  this  was  no  felony  if  the  barn 
was  neither  parcel  of  a  mansion  house  nor  full  of  corn.3  To  impute 
a  mere  intention  to  commit  a  crime  was  held  not  to  be  actionable, 
"  for  the  purpose  and  intent  of  a  man  without  act,  is  not  punish- 
able by  law";  and  that  was  so  even  though  the  act  charged 
might  be  punished  in  the  Star  Chamber,  "for  that  is  by  the 
absolute  power  of  the  Court  and  not  by  the  ordinary  course  of 
the  law."  4  Similarly,  to  accuse  a  man  of  an  impossible  crime,  as 
in  the  well-known  case  where  A  said  of  B,  that  B,  while  church- 
warden, had  stolen  the  bell-rope,  was  not  actionable.5  Fine 
distinctions  were  drawn  between  cases  where  subsequent  words 
explained  a  criminal  charge,  so  as  to  make  it  impossible,  and 
cases  when  they  merely  added  an  immaterial  detail,  so  as  to  leave 
it  possible.  To  say  "  thou  art  a  thief  and  hast  stolen  my  trees," 
was  actionable,  for  the  last  words  were  merely  an  addition  ; 6  but 
to  say  "  thou  art  a  thief  for  thou  hast  stolen  my  trees,"  was 
not  actionable,  for  the  last  words,  being  explanatory,  showed 
that  no  crime  had  been  committed.7  The  absurdity  of  applying 
such  distinctions  to  angry  words  spoken  in  heat  was  pointed  out 
by  Holt,  C.J.,8  and  is  obvious.  As  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  said,9  it 
followed  that  "  minute  and  copious  vituperation  was  safer  than 
terms  of  general  reproach,  such  as  '  thief,'  inasmuch  as  a  lay- 
man who  enters  on  details  will  probably  make  some  impossible 
combination." 

The  same  principles  were  applied  to  the  other  categories  of 
words  actionable  per  se.  Thus  to  say  of  a  man  that  he  was  full 
of  the  pox  was  not  actionable,  because  that  might  mean  merely 

1  Hext  v.  Yeomans  (1585)  4  Co.  Rep.  15b. 

2  Weaver  v.  Cariden  (1595)  4  Co.  Rep.  16a. 

3  Barham  v.  Nethersal  (1602)  4  Co.  Rep.  20a. 

4  Eaton  v.  Allen  (1598)  4  Co.  Rep.  16b. 

5  Jackson  v.  Adams  (1835)  2  Bing.  N.C.  402. 

6  Rolle,  Ab.  i  51,  R.  pi.  1.  7  Ibid  R.  pi.  2. 

8  "  The  opinions  of  later  times  have  been  in  many  instances  different  from  those 
of  former  days  in  relation  to  words,  for  formerly  there  has  been  a  difference  taken 
between  saying,  '  thou  art  a  thief  and  hast  stolen  my  wood,'  and  '  thou  art  a  thief  for 
thou  hast  stolen  my  wood  ' ;  and  judgments  have  gone  both  ways ;  but  later  opinions 
make  no  difference,  if  the  words  be  spoke  at  the  same  time.  And  these  are  scrambling 
things  that  have  gone  backwards  and  forwards,"  Baker  v.  Pierce  (1704)  6  Mod.  at 
pp.  23-24. 

9  Torts  (12th  ed.)  242. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  355 

smallpox.1  More  liberality  was  shown  in  the  case  of  words 
which  imputed  dishonesty  or  incapacity  in  a  trade  or  profession ; 
but  even  here  the  distinctions  ran  very  fine.  Thus  to  call  an 
attorney  corrupt  was  actionable,2  but  to  call  him  usurer,  or  to  say 
that,  being  an  executor,  he  would  not  perform  the  will,  was  not 
actionable.3  To  call  a  trader  bankrupt  was  actionable ; 4  but, 
according  to  some,  to  say  that  he  was  a  bankruptly  knave  was 
not,  as  the  words  did  not  mean  that  he  was  a  bankrupt,  but  only 
that  he  was  like  a  bankrupt5  As  the  words  must  cast  an  im- 
putation on  the  plaintiff  of  unfitness  for  his  particular  trade,  words 
which  would  be  defamatory  of  one  person  might  not  be  defamatory 
of  another.  Thus  to  call  an  attorney  or  a  justice  of  the  peace  a 
common  barrator  was  actionable ; 6  but  it  was  not  actionable  to 
apply  the  same  term  to  a  common  carrier.7  Obviously  a  man 
who  knew  the  trade  or  profession  of  the  person  whom  he  wished 
to  abuse,  could,  if  he  chose  his  words  with  care,  indulge  with 
impunity  in  a  considerable  latitude  of  vituperation. 

The  application  of  these  principles  was  partly  the  cause,  and 
partly  the  effect,  of  the  general  doctrine  that  in  these  actions  the 
words  complained  of  must  be  construed,  not  in  their  natural  sense, 
but,  whenever  possible,  in  "mitiore  sensu."  That  is,  they  must 
be  held  not  to  be  defamatory  if  a  non-defamatory  sense  could  be 
twisted  out  of  them.  This  principle  is  taken  for  granted  by 
Coke ; 8  and,  if  it  had  been  limited  to  the  case  where  the  words 
were  really  of  doubtful  meaning,  it  would  have  been  unobjection- 
able. The  rule  was,  it  is  true,  stated  in  this  way  by  Coke,9 
Rolle,10  and  March,11  in  the  first  half  of  the  seventeenth  century. 
But  the  judges,  in  their  desire  to  discourage  these  actions,  did  not 
so  limit  it.     They  examined  the  words  in  the  same  manner  as 

1  James  v.  Rutledge  (1599)  Moore  573 ;  S.C.  4  Co.  Rep.  17a. 

3  Birchley's  Case  (1585)  4  Co.  Rep.  16a.  3  Ibid. 

4  Kempe's  Case  (1553)  Dyer  72b  ;  4  Co.  Rep.  19a. 

5  Rolle,  Ab.  i  47  I.  pi.  3,  citing  a  case  of  1608 ;  Selby  v.  Carrier  (1615)  Cro.  Jac. 
345 ;  sed  contra  4  Co.  Rep.  19a,  if  the  words  imply  an  act  done  and  not  merely  an 
inclination  to  do  an  act,  and  with  this  view  the  Court  agreed  in  Booth  v.  Scale  (1663) 
1  Sid.  103. 

6  Rolle,  Ab.  i  54,  S.  pi.  15.  »  Ibid  j  5g>  v.  pi.  3. 

8  "  And  it  was  said  quod  sensus  verborum  est  duplex,  scil.  mitis  et  asper ;  et 
verba  semper  accipienda  sunt  in  mitiori  sensu,"  Cromwell's  Case  (1578-81)  4  Co.  Rep. 
at  f.  13a ;  ibid  at  fF.  15b,  17b,  20a. 

* "  Wc  will  not  give  more  favour  unto  actions  upon  the  case  foT  words  than  of 
necessity  we  ought  to  do,  -.tliere  the  words  are  not  apparently  scandalous,"  Crofts  v. 
Brown  (1617)  3  Buls.  167. 

10  "  Lou  les  parols  sont  dubious  et  poient  receiver  un  double  interpretacion  lun  voie 
que  ils  serront  actionable  et  l'autre  nemy,  ils  serront  prise  en  mitiori  sensu,"  Rolle, 
Ab.  i  71,  Z.  pi.  1. 

11 1«  \\re  have  a  rule  that  words,  if  they  admit  of  a  double  construction,  shall 
always  be  taken  in  the  best  sense  for  him  that  speaks  them.  .  .  .  This  I  say  the  law 
doth  when  the  words  are  amphibolus,  but  if  the  words  are  clearly  actionable,  in  such 
case  the  law  will  never  aid  a  man,"  Actions  for  Slaunder  5. 


356  CRIME  AND  TORT 

they  were  accustomed  to  examine  a  writ  or  a  pleading,  in  order 
to  discover,  if  possible,  a  non-defamatory  sense ;  and,  as  they 
were  experts  in  this  art  of  critically  examining  words,  it  was  not 
difficult  to  find  a  non-defamatory  sense  in  the  most  insulting 
words.  Indeed,  it  would  seem  that  the  result  of  an  action  often 
depended  on  the  comparative  ingenuity  of  the  counsel  in  suggest- 
ing interpretations  of  the  words  used.  Two  instances  will  suffice. 
"If  one  man  says  of  another,  'Thou  art  a  prigging  pilfering 
merchant  and  hast  pilfered  away  my  corn  and  my  goods  from  my 
wife  and  my  servants  and  this  I  will  prove,'  no  action  lies  for  that 
(as  it  seems),  nor  does  it  appear  that  he  intended  that  he  had 
taken  these  goods  feloniously,  and  therefore  the  words  shall  be 
taken  in  mitori  sensu."  1  "  If  a  man  says  of  A,  'he  was  a  pick- 
pocket, and  had  picked  my  pocket,  and  took  12s.  of  money  out  of 
my  pocket,' 2  no  action  lies  for  these  words,  because  it  might  be 
done  merely  as  a  trespass  or  in  jest  and  not  feloniously."3  A 
long  lins  of  similar  cases  are  reported  in  the  books ;  and  in  spite 
of  attempts  in  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  and  in  the 
eighteenth  centuries  to  restrict  this  vicious  system  of  interpre- 
tation,4 and  to  put  the  law  upon  a  more  sensible  basis,  it  still 
continued.  "  It  is  only  in  comparatively  recent  times  that  the 
perverse  subtlety  of  special  pleading,  by  which  this  branch  of  the 
law  was  specially  encumbered,  has  altogether  disappeared"  ; 5  for, 
as  we  shall  see,6  it  is  not  till  comparatively  recent  times  that  the 
Courts  have  ceased  to  look  at  the  cases  in  order  to  come  to  a 
conclusion  as  to  whether  the  words  used  are  or  are  not  defamatory. 
We  shall  now  see  that  the  effect  of  these  principles  was 
aggravated  by  equally  restrictive  rules  as  to  the  persons  liable  for 
the  repetition  of  a  slander,  as  to  the  kinds  of  damage  for  which  the 
action  lay,  and  as  to  the  kinds  of  damage  which  the  courts  allowed 
to  be  the  natural  and  probable  consequence  of  the  defamation. 

1  Rolle,  Ab.  i  73,  Z.  pi.  14. 

2  Ibid  Z.  pi.  20 ;  and  see  also  below  360.  3  Ibid. 

4  "  And  tho'  in  the  old  books  the  rule  was  to  take  the  words  in  mitiori  sensu,  yet 
by  Holt,  C.J.,  they  would  give  no  favour  to  words,  and  should  give  satisfaction  to 
them  whose  reputation  is  hurt ;  and  would  take  words  in  a  common  sense  according 
to  the  vulgar  intendment  of  the  bystanders.  The  rule  de  mitiori  sensu  is  to  be 
understood  when  the  words  in  their  natural  import  are  doubtful,  and  equally  to  be 
understood  in  the  one  sense  as  in  the  other,"  Somers  v.  House  (1694)  Holt  39;  "I 
have  heard  my  Lord  Hale  and  Justice  Twisden  say  that  they  knew  no  set  rule  for 
actions  for  words,  "but  that  all  words  stood  upon  their  own  feet,"  Baker  v.  Pierce 
(1704)  6  Mod.  at  p.  24  per  Holt,  C.J. ;  "  men's  tongues  growing  more  virulent,  and 
irreparable  damage  arising  from  words,  it  has  been  by  experience  found,  that  unless 
men  can  get  satisfaction  by  law,  they  will  be  apt  to  take  it  themselves.  The  rule 
therefore  that  has  now  prevailed  is,  that  words  are  to  be  taken  in  that  sense  that  is 
most  natural  and  obvious,  and  in  which  those  to  whom  they  are  spoken  will  be  sure 
to  understand  them,"  Harrison  v.  Thornborough  (1714)  10  Mod.  at  p.  198;  cp. 
Carpenter  v.  Tarrent  (1737)  Cas.  t.  Hardwicke  per  Lord  Hardwicke,  C.J. 

s  Clerk  and  Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  563. 

6  Below  358-359- 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  357 

(J>)  One  effect  of  the  line  of  cases,  which  has  just  been  dis- 
cussed, was  to  make  it  unnecessary,  in  many  instances,  to  consider 
whether  or  not  the  plaintiff  had  suffered  damage.  The  words 
were  held  not  to  be  defamatory,  and  that  was  the  end  of  the  case.1 
But  even  if  the  plaintiff  could  prove  that  he  had  been  defamed  and 
had  suffered  damage,  his  difficulties  were  not  at  an  end.  Firstly, 
it  was  laid  down  by  Coke  in  the  Earl  of  Northampton  s  Case'  that, 
"if  J.S.  publish  that  he  hath  heard  J.N.  say  that  J.G.  was  a  traitor 
or  thief,  in  an  action  of  the  case,  if  the  truth  be  such,  he  may 
justify.  But  if  J.S.  publish  that  he  hath  heard  generally  without 
a  certain  author,  that  J.G.  was  a  traitor  or  thief,  there  an  action 
sur  le  case  lieth  against  J.S.  for  this,  that  he  hath  not  given  to  the 
party  grieved  any  cause  of  action  against  any,  but  against  himself 
who  published  the  words,  although  that  in  truth  he  might  hear 
them."  This  was  long  regarded  as  settled  law,3  and  was  not  over- 
ruled till  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century.4  It  is  not 
till  then  that  we  begin  to  get  the  development  of  the  modern  rules 
as  to  when  a  person  is  liable  for  slander,  when  damage  has  been 
caused  by  its  repetition  by  other  persons.5  Secondly,  the  damage 
must  be  ascertainable  temporal  damage.  Thus  it  was  held  in 
16696  that  to  say  of  a  virgin  of  good  fame,  "she  was  with  child 
by  Simons,"  whereby  she  lost  her  parent's  favour,  was  not  action- 
able. This  rule  was  no  doubt  due  in  part  to  the  rule  that  defama- 
tion, which  alleged  offences  cognizable  only  in  the  ecclesiastical 
courts,  and  unaccompanied  by  temporal  damage,  was  not 
actionable  at  common  law."  But,  as  the  case  of  Lynch  v.  Knight* 
in  1 86 1  shows,  the  rule  long  worked  hardship;  and  it  has  only 
partially  been  remedied  by  the  Slander  of  Women  Act  1891,9  in 
the  case  of  the  one  particular  class  of  slander  in  which  the  rule 
worked  the  greatest  hardship.  Moreover,  the  existence  of  the 
damage  must  be  strictly  proved — "  when  the  speaking  of  the  words 
might  be  a  damage  to  the  plaintiff,  yet  if  the  ground  of  that 
damnification  do  not  sufficiently  appear  by  the  record,  the  action 

1  Bramston,  C.J.,  once  went  so  far  as  to  say  that,  if  the  words  did  not  import  a 
scandal  in  themselves,  the  averment  of  a  particular  damage  could  not  make  them 
actionable ;  but  no  one  else  seems  to  have  taken  this  extreme  view,  March,  Actions  for 
Slaunder  102. 

2  (1613)  12  Co.  Rep.  at  p.  134. 

3  See  Davis  v.  Lewis  (1796)  7  T.R.  17. 

4  McPherson  v.  Daniels  (1829)  10  B.  and  C.  263. 

5  See  Ratcliffe  v.  Evans  [1892]  2  Q.B.  at  p.  530,  where  Bowen,  L.J.,  lays  it  down 
that,  *'  Verbal  defamatory  statements  may  be  intended  to  be  repeated,  or  may  be 
uttered  under  such  circumstances  that  their  repetition  follows  in  the  ordinary  course  of 
things  from  their  original  utterance.  Except  in  such  cases,  the  law  does  not  allow  the 
plaintiff  to  recover  damages  which  flow,  not  from  the  original  slander,  but  from  its  un- 
authorised repetition." 

11  Barnes  v.  Bruddel  1  Lev.  261.  »  Above  348 

8  9  H.L.C.  577-  9  54,  55  Victoria  c.  51. 


358  CRIME  AND  TORT 

will  not  lie."  1  Thirdly,  we  have  seen  that,  though  the  defamation 
imputed  only  an  offence  cognizable  in  the  ecclesiastical  courts,  yet 
if  it  was  followed  by  damage,  an  action  lay — e.g.  the  imputation 
of  unchastity  to  a  woman  whereby  she  lost  her  marriage." 
Similarly  it  was  held  that,  where  the  plaintiff's  shepherd  falsely 
and  maliciously  told  the  bailiff  of  the  manor  that  one  of  the  plaintiff's 
sheep  was  an  estray,  whereupon  the  bailiff  seized  it,  this  damage  was 
attributable  to  these  words,  and  made  them  actionable.3  But  it 
was  laid  down  in  Vicars  v.  Wilcocks 4  that,  if  in  consequence  of  the 
words  spoken,  another  does  an  act  which  would  be  illegal,  even 
assuming  that  the  words  were  true,  no  action  lay.  it  is  probable 
that  this  decision  was  based  on  somewhat  the  same  ground  as  the 
decision  in  the  Earl  of  Northampton's  Case}1  Just  as  in  that  case 
the  person  slandered  was  only  allowed  to  recover  against  the 
originator  of  the  slander,  and  not  against  the  person  who  had 
repeated  it,  so,  according  to  this  decision,  he  was  only  allowed  to 
recover  against  the  man  who  had  done  the  illegal  act  which  had 
damaged  him,  and  not  against  the  person  who  had  uttered  the 
slander,  which  had  caused  the  illegal  act  to  be  done.  The  law  in 
the  one  case  allowed  an  action  against  the  originator  of  the  slander, 
and  in  the  other  case  against  the  person  who  had  done  the  illegal 
act.  It  refused  to  allow  any  other  action,  and  so  the  slanderer 
went  free.  But  it  is  probable  that  this  hard  and  fast  rule  is  as 
obsolete  as  the  rule  laid  down  in  the  Earl  of  Northampton  s  Case.6 
The  true  test  is,  as.  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  pointed  out,7  not  whether 
the  act  done  was  legal  or  illegal,  but  whether  the  act,  whether 
legal  or  illegal,  was  the  natural  and  probable  consequence  of  the 
slander. 

All  these  evil  results,  which  flowed  from  the  attempts  of  the 
judges  to  discourage  these  actions  for  defamation,  were  aggravated 
by  the  accumulation  of  cases  in  the  reports,  in  which  the  courts 
had  construed  this  or  that  specimen  of  abuse  to  be  or  not  to  be 
defamatory.  We  have  seen  that  the  practice  of  reporting  cases, 
which  turned  on  the  construction  of  particular  documents,  tended 

1  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  49  ;  a  fortiori  if  it  appeared  by  the  record  that  there 
was  no  damage — "  if  one  say  of  a  woman  that  '  she  hath  murdered  her  husband  ' ;  and 
she  and  her  husband  bring  the  action,  it  will  not  lie,  because  it  doth  appear  by  the 
record  that  the  slander  is  not  prejudicial,"  ibid.,  citing  a  case  of  1608. 

-  Above  350.  3  Newman  v.  Zachary  (1647)  Aleyn  3. 

4  (1806)  8  East  1 — "  the  special  damage  must  be  the  legal  and  natural  consequence 
of  the  words  spoken,  otherwise  it  did  not  sustain  the  declaration  :  and  here  it  was  an 
illegal  consequence  ;  a  mere  wrongful  act  of  the  master  ;  for  which  the  defendant  was 
no  more  answerable,  than  if  in  consequence  of  the  words,  other  persons  had  afterwards 
assembled  and  seized  the  plaintiff,  and  thrown  him  into  a  horsepond  by  way  of  punish- 
ment for  his  supposed  transgression,"  per  Lord  Ellenborough,  C.J. 

5  (1613)  12  Co.  Rep.  132. 

6  See  the  remarks  of  Lord  Wensleydale  in  Lynch  v.  Knight  (1861)  9  H.L.C.  at 
p.  600. 

7  Torts  (12th  ed.)  240. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  359 

to  create  all  sorts  of  arbitrary  rules  for  the  interpretation  of  these 
documents  ;  that  the  status  of  these  rules  was  often  uncertain — it 
was  not  clear  whether  they  were  rules  of  law,  or  rules  of  construc- 
tion, or  merely  inferences  of  fact  as  to  the  interpretation  ot  the 
particular  document  before  the  court ;  and  that  the  application  of 
these  rules  often  tended  to  frustrate  the  intentions  of  the  parties  to 
these  documents.1  Similar  evil  effects  followed  these  numerous 
reports  of  actions  for  defamatory  words.  A  very  cursory  glance 
at  Rolle's  and  the  later  Abridgments,  will  show  that  this  practice 
of  piling  up  cases,  which  turned  on  the  construction  of  particular 
words,  had  a  disastrous  effect  on  this  branch  of  the  law.  Rolle 
tried  to  reduce  them  to  some  sort  of  order  by  grouping  them  under 
general  headings.  Thus  he  has  a  long  list  of  cases  turning  on  the 
imputation  of  perjury  ;  on  more  general  words  of  abuse  ;  on  words 
which  do  not  impute  felony  but  only  minor  offences  ;  on  adjective 
interrogative  conditional  and  disjunctive  words,  and  words  in  the 
past  tense  ;  on  words  which  are  not  directly  affirmative  ;  on  words 
imputing  a  criminal  intention ;  on  cases  in  which  later  words  will 
explain  and  modify  the  effect  of  former  words  ;  on  words  imputing 
disgraceful  conduct  in  one's  profession  office  or  trade ;  on  words 
which  will  support  an  action  in  spite  of  their  uncertainty  ;  on  cases 
where  the  words  will  be  taken  in  mitiore  sensu ;  on  cases  where 
the  action  lies  though  the  words  are  repugnant,  though  the  person 
slandered  is  not  directly  described,  or  though  the  charge  is  not 
quite  precisely  made ;  on  cases  in  which  an  averment  would,  and 
cases  in  which  it  would  not,  render  words  actionable.  A  study  of 
those  cases  makes  it  quite  obvious  that  so  many  and  such  fine  dis- 
tinctions were  drawn  by  the  judges  as  to  the  actionable  quality  of 
words,  that  it  was  a  mere  lottery  whether  or  no  any  particular 
words  would  be  held  to  be  defamatory ;  and  although,  as  we  have 
seen,  protests  were  made  in  the  late  seventeenth  and  the  eighteenth 
centuries  against  this  vicious  system  of  citing  cases  to  prove  that 
this  or  that  set  of  words  were  or  were  not  defamatory,2  it  was  not 
till  modern  times  that  it  was  eliminated,  by  the  application  to 
words  and  writings,  which  were  the  subjects  of  actions  for  defama- 
tion, of  the  rule  that  the  meaning  of  all  words  and  documents  is  a 
question  of  fact  to  be  deduced  from  the  words  and  the  documents 
themselves.3 

The  best  proof  of  the  absurd  results  of  this  practice  is  the 
cases  themselves ;  and  as  illustrations  I  will  take  one  or  two  cases 
from  Croke's  reports  of  James  I.'s  reign. 

In  the  following  cases  the  words  were  held  to  be  defamatory  : — 
Words  spoken  of  a  justice  of  the  peace,   stating   that  he  had 

1  Vol.  vii.  392-394.  2  Above  356  n.  4. 

3  Above  356 ;  see  Lord  Halsbury's  Laws  of  England  xviii  639  n.  (t). 


360  CRIME  AND  TORT 

instigated  others  to  attempt  to  murder  the  speaker,  were  held  to  be 
actionable  by  three  judges  against  two.1  Words  spoken  of  a 
commissioner  to  examine  witnesses,  imputing  that  he  had  taken 
bribes  to  favour  one  of  the  parties,  were  held  actionable  by  four 
judges  against  one.2  The  statement  that  a  justice  of  the  peace 
was  "  a  partial  justice  "  was  held  actionable  by  the  two  judges  who 
tried  the  case.3  To  accuse  a  man  of  having  robbed  the  church, 
and  stolen  lead  from  it,  was  held  actionable  by  three  judges  against 
two ;  but  no  action  would  have  lain  if  the  words  had  been  "  thou 
hast  robbed  the  church  for  thou  hast  stolen  lead,"  because  there 
could  be  no  larceny  of  the  lead  which  was  fixed  to  the  freehold.4 

In  the  following  cases  the  words  were  held  not  to  be  de- 
famatory : — It  was  held  by  three  judges  to  two  that,  to  say  of  a 
magistrate  that  "  he  is  a  rascally  villain,  and  keeps  a  company  of 
thieves  and  traitors  to  do  mischief,"  was  not  actionable ; 5  and 
again  by  three  judges  to  two  that  it  was  not  actionable  to  say 
' '  thou  art  a  thievish  knave  and  hath  stolen  my  wood,"  as  "  stealing 
of  wood  may  be  intended  growing  wood,  and  then  it  is  not  any 
felony,  and  so  no  cause  of  action."  6  On  the  same  principle  it 
was  held  not  actionable  to  charge  a  man  with  having  stolen  iron 
bars  from  windows,  or  corn  from  a  field.7  But,  perhaps,  the  most 
absurd  of  all  these  cases  is  the  following:8  the  words  were,  "Sir 
Thomas  Holt  struck  his  cook  on  the  head  with  a  cleaver,  and 
cleaved  his  head ;  the  one  part  lay  on  the  one  shoulder  and  the 
other  on  the  other" — as  clear  an  accusation  of  homicide,  one 
could  think,  as  could  be  desired.  But  "it  was  moved  in  arrest  of 
judgment  that  these  words  were  not  actionable,  for  it  is  not  averred 
that  the  cook  was  killed,  but  argumentative.  The  Court  was  of 
that  opinion,  Fleming,  Chief  Justice,  and  Williams  absentibus  ;  for 
slander  ought  to  be  direct,  against  which  there  may  not  be  any 
intendment:  but  here  notwithstanding  such  wounding  the  party 
may  yet  be  living ;  and  it  is  then  but  trespass." 

It  is  clear  that  an  action  which  had  given  rise  to  such  a  body 
of  law  as  this,  gave  no  adequate  remedy  'for  defamation.  No 
doubt  in  the  early  part  of  the  seventeenth  century  its  inadequacy 
was  mitigated  by  the  fact  that  proceedings  might  be  taken  in  the 
court  of  Star  Chamber.9  But,  when  the  Star  Chamber  was 
abolished,  a  new  and  better  remedy  was  imperatively  needed. 
We  shall  now  see  that  it  was  mainly  for  this  reason  that,  after  the 
Restoration,  the  courts  began  to  treat  the  tort  of  libel  in  a 
different  way  from  the  tort  of  slander.    The  old  unsatisfactory  law 

1  Harper  v.  Beamond  (1605)  Cro.  Jac.  56. 

2  Moor  v.  Foster  (1606)  ibid  65.  s  Kemp  v.  Housgoe  (1606)  ibid  90. 
4  Benson  v.  Morley  (1608)  ibid  153.            6  Hollis  v.  Briscow  (1605)  ibid.  58. 

6  Robins  v.  Hildredon  (1608)  ibid  65.  7  Powell  v.  Hutchins  (1609)  ibid  204. 

8  Holt  v.  Astgrigg  (1608)  ibid  184.  9  Vol.  v.  208-212. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  361 

was  still  applied  to  spoken  defamation ;  but  some  very  different 
rules  were  applied  to  defamation  which  was  written.  These 
rules  eventually  reacted  on  the  tort  of  slander,  and  effected  some 
improvement  in  the  law ;  but  the  unfortunate  distinction  between 
written  and  spoken  defamation,  due  ultimately  to  the  treatment 
of  the  action  on  the  case  by  the  judges  of  the  early  years  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  and  immediately  to  the  remedy  for  that 
treatment  adopted  by  the  judges  of  the  latter  part  of  that  century, 
still  remains  to  trouble  the  law. 

(2)  The  origin  of  the  difference  between  libel  and  slander. 

The  abolition  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  court  of  Star  Chamber, 
and  the  absorption  of  some  parts  of  it  by  the  common  law  courts 
after  the  Restoration,  created  a  difficult  problem  in  connection 
with  several  wrongs  or  offences  which  hover  on  the  border  line 
between  crime  and  tort.  This  problem  can  be  stated  as  follows  : 
There  were  several  of  these  wrongs  or  offences,  notably  defama- 
tion conspiracy  and  maintenance,  as  to  which  the  common  law, 
because  it  had  provided  a  civil  or  a  criminal  remedy,  had,  in  the 
mediaeval  period  and  later,  acquired  a  certain  number  of  rules.1 
But,  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries,  the  law  as  to 
these  wrongs  or  offences  had  been  further  developed  by  the  court 
of  Star  Chamber ;  and  this  development  had  been  concerned 
mainly  with  their  criminal  aspect.2  It  followed  that,  when  the  com- 
mon law  courts  took  over  these  parts  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Star 
Chamber,  it  took  over  the  law  relating  to  the  wrongs  or  offences 
which  had  been  there  developed.  They  became  common  law  mis- 
demeanours ;  and  the  definition  of  these  misdemeanours  owed 
something  both  to  the  common  law  rules  and  to  the  rules  of  the 
Star  Chamber.  How  much  they  owed  to  these  two  sets  of  in- 
fluences varied  in  each  case.  In  the  case  of  the  criminal  aspect  of 
defamation 3  and  conspiracy4  the  debt  owed  to  the  Star  Chamber  was 
large,  and  that  owed  to  the  common  law  was  comparatively  small. 
In  the  case  of  the  civil  aspect  of  defamation,  and  of  the  civil  and 
criminal  aspect  of  maintenance,5  the  influence  of  common  law  rules 
was  more  prominent ;  and  we  shall  see  that,  for  a  considerable 
period,  the  same  thing  can  be  said  of  the  civil  aspect  of  conspiracy.6 
Now,  when  all  these  three  wrongs  or  offences  came  to  be  recog- 
nized as  common  law  misdemeanours,  two  questions  naturally 
arose.  Firstly,  could  all  these  criminal  offences  be  regarded  as 
torts  ?  and,  if  so,  were  the  incidents  of  these  offences,  regarded  as 

1  For  the  mediaeval  rules  as  to  conspiracy  and  maintenance  see  vol.  iii  395-399, 
401-407  ;  for  the  rules  as  to  defamation  see  vol.  iii  409-411 ;  above  335. 

2  Vol.  v.  201-205,  208-212. 

3  Above  336,  338  seqq.  *  Below  379-384. 
5  Below  397-400.                                              «  Below  392-393. 


362  CRIME  AND  TORT 

torts,  in  all  respects  the  same  as  the  incidents  of  these  offences  re- 
garded as  crimes  ?  Secondly,  were  they  torts  like  trespass,  which 
would  give  rise  to  an  action  for  nominal  damages  ?  or  were  they 
torts  like  negligence,  which  would  only  give  rise  to  an  action  if  the 
plaintiff  could  show  that  he  had  suffered  damage?  In  other  words, 
was  the  act  per  se  tortious,  or  was  it  only  tortious  if  accompanied 
by  damage  ? 

These  problems  were  raised  by  the  historical  development  of 
the  law  on  these  subjects.  But  there  is  no  reason  to  think  that 
the  judges  realized  their  precise  nature ;  and  it  is  certain  that  they 
did  not  try  to  solve  them  on  any  general  or  theoretical  grounds. 
As  must  necessarily  happen  under  a  system  of  case  law,  they  de- 
cided the  cases  as  they  arose  in  the  manner  which  seemed  to  them 
most  expedient,  and  for  reasons  which  seemed  sufficient  to  dispose 
of  the  case  in  hand.  The  result  has  been  that  they  have  left 
undecided  many  points  which,  in  later  years,  have  given  rise  to 
much  difference  of  professional  and  judicial  opinion.  Controversy 
upon  these  points  has  often  not  been  illuminating,  and  the  decisions 
arrived  at  have  not  always  been  convincing,  mainly  because  the 
historical  causes,  and  therefore  the  real  nature  of  the  problem,  have 
not  been  clearly  realized — a  fact  of  which  the  conflicting  decisions 
in  the  case  of  Neville  v.  London  Express  Newspaper  Ltd.}  and  the 
long  unsettled  question  of  the  nature  of  the  tort  of  conspiracy,2  are 
leading  illustrations.  But,  even  if  the  judges  of  the  seventeenth 
century  had  realized  the  true  nature  of  the  problem,  and  had 
approached  it  from  its  theoretical  side,  it  would  have  been  found 
difficult  to  solve,  because  many  good  reasons  could  be  given  for 
opposite  solutions. 

(i)  Could  all  those  criminal  offences  be  regarded  as  torts  ?  and, 
if  so,  were  the  incidents  of  these  offences,  regarded  as  torts,  in  all 
respects  the  same  as  the  incidents  of  these  offences  regarded  as 
crimes  ? 

In  favour  of  the  view  that  all  these  offences  should  be 
regarded  as  torts,  it  could  be  argued  that  they  were  all  treated 
by  the  law  as  criminal  offences ;  and  that,  if  an  act  so  treated 
caused  damage  to  another,  that  other  ought  to  have  an  action  for 
damages.  Moreover,  it  could  be  argued  that  this  was  the  right 
solution  on  historical  grounds,  because,  firstly,  the  common  and 
statute  law  had  recognized,  in  the  case  of  conspiracy  and  mainten- 
ance, that  these  offences  could  give  rise  to  proceedings  in  the 
nature  of  trespass,  which,  like  trespass,  were  as  much  civil  in  their 
nature  as  criminal ; 3  and,  secondly,  because  the  court  of  Star 
Chamber  sometimes  gave  damages  to  the  person  injured  by  al! 

1  [1919]  A.C.  368.  2  Below  394-397. 

a  Vol.  iii  397-398»  4°4-4°7- 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  363 

these  offences.1  On  the  other  hand,  it  might  be  said  that  the  mere 
fact  that  the  law  chose,  from  motives  of  public  policy,  to  treat  a 
given  course  of  conduct  as  a  criminal  offence,  did  not  necessarily 
prove  that  the  law  would  regard  it  as  a  tort ;  and  that,  even  admitting 
that  these  wrongful  acts  should  be  regarded  as  torts  if  they  caused 
damage  to  another,  it  did  not  follow  that  the  tort  would  neces- 
sarily have  the  same  incidents  as  the  criminal  offence  which  had 
been  developed  by  the  court  of  Star  Chamber.  This  truth  was 
realized  in  the  case  of  defamation,  as  the  differences  between  the 
tort  and  the  crime  of  libel  testify.2  The  failure  to  realize  it  in  the 
case  of  maintenance  is  at  the  bottom  of  the  inconsistent  opinions 
in  the  case  of  Neville  v,  London  Express  Newspaper  Ltd.  ; 3  and, 
as  we  shall  see,  it  has  something  to  do  with  the  obscurity  which 
long  hung  about  the  question  whether  there  is  such  a  thing  as  the 
tort  of  conspiracy.4 

(ii)  Were  these  torts  torts  like  trespass,  which  would  give  rise 
to  an  action  for  nominal  damages  ?  or  were  they  torts  like 
negligence,  which  would  only  give  rise  to  an  action  if  the  plaintiff 
could  show  that  he  had  suffered  damage? 

If  these  wrongs  could  be  regarded  as  torts,  there  was  something 
to  be  said  in  favour  of  the  view  that  they  should  be  so  regarded, 
whether  damage  resulted  or  not,  so  that  they  would  give  rise 
to  a  right  of  action  for  nominal  damages,  because  from  them 
general  damage  could  be  presumed.  They  were  obvious  abuses  of 
so  serious  a  kind  that  the  state  had  deemed  it  expedient  to  treat 
them  as  crimes.  Why  should  they  not  be  regarded  as  involv- 
ing a  tort  of  this  character  ?  It  might  be  argued  that  they  should 
be  regarded  as  involving  a  tort  of  this  character,  just  as  larceny 
involves  a  trespass.  On  the  other  hand,  it  might  be  said  that  the 
form  of  action  by  which  these  torts  were  remedied  was  Case ;  and 
that  that  necessarily  involved  the  conclusion  that  they  were  only 
torts  if  the  plaintiff  could  show  that  he  had  suffered  damage.  No 
doubt  this  is  a  technical  reason ;  but,  in  support  of  it,  it  might  be 
argued  that,  though  it  might  be  expedient  to  treat  these  wrongs 
as  crimes,  there  was  no  reason  to  treat  them  as  torts  unless  a 
plaintiff  could  show  that  he  had  suffered  damage — a  line  of 
reasoning  which  is  fully  admitted  in  the  rule,  laid  down  at  the  end 
of  this  period,  that  a  public  nuisance  will  not  give  rise  to  an 
action  in  tort  in  the  absence  of  special  damage.5  We  shall  see 
that  this  line  of  reasoning  has  been  followed  in  the  case  of  the 
torts  of  conspiracy  fi  and  maintenance.7     On  the  other  hand,  in  the 

1  Vol.  v  211-212.  2  Above  339. 

3  tI9I9]  A.C.  368  ;  below  400-402.  *  Below  392-397. 

5  Iveson  v.  Moore  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  486. 

6  Below  394,  396-397.  »  Below  400. 


364  CRIME  AND  TORT 

case  of  written  as  opposed  to  spoken  defamation,  the  first  line  of 
reasoning  was  followed.  We  shall  see  that  in  the  case  of  libel,  as 
distinct  from  slander,  the  courts,  after  the  Restoration,  held  that 
no  special  damage  need  be  shown  to  ground  the  action1 — that 
libel  was  a  wrongful  act  from  which  damage  could  be  presumed. 

If  we  took  a  narrow  historical  view  of  the  development  of 
these  torts,  we  might  wonder  at  the  conclusion  thus  reached.  It 
might  be  said  that  the  early  common  law  remedies,  both  in  the 
case  of  conspiracy  and  maintenance,  showed  that,  being  wrongs  in 
the  nature  of  trespass,  they  should  have  been  regarded  as  torts  of 
the  nature  of  trespass,  that  is  as  violations  of  absolute  rights ; 
while  defamation,  spoken  or  written,  being  redressible  at  common 
law  only  by  an  action  on  the  case,  should  not  have  been  regarded 
as  giving  rise  to  an  action  in  tort  in  the  absence  of  special  damage. 
But  to  reason  in  this  way  would  be  to  ignore,  both  the  manner  in 
which  the  Star  Chamber  had  developed  all  these  wrongs  in  the 
sixteenth  century,  and  the  new  conditions  which  the  problem  had, 
in  consequence,  assumed  after  the  Restoration.  The  judges,  as  I 
have  already  said,  were  not  fully  conscious  of  the  problem  in  all 
its  bearings  ;  but,  when  faced  with  the  question  whether,  in  any 
particular  case,  written  defamation,  or  conspiracy,  or  maintenance 
should  give  rise  to  an  action  in  tort,  they  answered  it  in  a  manner 
seemed  to  them  to  be  most  expedient. 

Now  in  considering  the  question  whether  written  defamation 
should  give  rise  to  an  action  in  tort  without  proof  of  special 
damage,  the  judges  had  before  them  the  following  three  facts : 
firstly,  such  defamation  was  a  crime ;  secondly,  the  development 
of  the  action  on  the  case  had  made  this  action  a  wholly  unsatis- 
factory remedy  for  the  tort  of  defamation  ;  thirdly,  if  the  prevalent 
habit  of  duelling  was  to  be  suppressed,  some  better  remedy  must 
be  provided.  We  know  that  the  last  two  considerations  had  in- 
duced them  to  try  to  improve  the  conditions  under  which  the 
action  on  the  case  lay  ; 2  and,  though  there  is  no  direct  evidence 
as  to  their  reasons  for  deciding  that  written,  unlike  spoken  defama- 
tion, would  give  rise  to  an  action  without  proof  of  special  damage, 
I  cannot  help  thinking  that  it  was  the  combined  weight  of  all 
these  three  reasons  which  induced  them  to  reform  the  law  by 
drawing  this  distinction.  However  that  may  be,  the  cases  make 
it  quite  clear  that  this  distinction  was  drawn  in  the  latter  half  of 
the  sevententh  century. 

The  earliest  decision  is  the  case  of  King  v.  Lake  in  167c3 
Hale,  C.B.,  held  that,  "although  general  words  spoken  once 
without  writing  or  publishing  them  would  not  be  actionable ;  yet 

1  Below  365.  2  Above  356  n.  4. 

3  Hardres  470. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  365 

here,  they  being  writ  and  published,  which  contains  more  malice, 
than  if  they  had  been  once  spoken,  they  are  actionable  "  ;  and  this 
decision  was  affirmed  on  a  writ  of  error.1  It  was  followed  in  1683 
in  the  case  of  Austin  v.  Culpepper*  In  the  eighteenth  century 
these  decisions  were  followed  in  the  cases  of  Harntan  v.  Delany,3 
and  Villers  v.  Monsley*  though  one  of  the  judges  in  the  latter  case 
seemed  to  think  that  the  authority  for  the  distinction  between 
written  and  spoken  defamation  was  somewhat  slender.5  The  rule 
was  finally  settled  in  181 2,  after  a  full  consideration  of  the  cases, 
by  the  decision  of  the  Exchequer  Chamber  in  the  case  of  Thorley 
v.  Kerry.6  Mansfield,  C.J.,  held  with  regret  that  the  distinction 
between  spoken  and  written  defamation,  though  indefensible  in 
principle,"  was  too  well  established  to  be  repudiated. 

It  cannot  be  doubted  that  this  decision  of  the  judges  of  the 
latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century  to  treat  libel  as  an  inde- 
pendent tort,  for  which  a  plaintiff  could  recover  damages  without 
the  need  for  proving  special  damage,  had  the  results  which  were 
intended.  In  the  first  place,  though  the  damage  and  not  the  in- 
sult was  still  the  gist  of  the  action,  the  fact  that  the  publication  of 
written  defamation  was  regarded  as  a  wrong  to  reputation  from 
which  damage  could  be  presumed,  naturally  tended  to  make  the 
insult  a  more  prominent  element  in  the  tort  than  the  damage ;  and 
so  tended  to  put  the  tort  upon  a  more  satisfactory  footing.8  In  the 
second  place,  once  the  libel  was  proved,  the  defendant  was  shown 
to  be  a  wrongdoer,  and  the  plaintiff  could  recover  damages  because 
the  commission  of  such  a  wrong  implies  damage.  There  was  no 
need,  as  in  the  case  of  slander,  to  allege  the  special  damage  suffered 
with  particularity,  and  prove  that  it  had  been  suffered.  This  dif- 
ference between  an  act  which  was  in  itself  wrongful,  and  an  act 
which  was  only  wrongful  if  it  caused  damage,  was  recognized  in 
the  case  of  Iveson  v.  Moore  in  1 700 ; 9  and  it  gave  rise  to  one  of 
the  most  beneficial  effects  of  thus  treating  libel  as  a  wrong  in  itself 
— the  emancipation  of  the  court  from  that  long  series  of  cases,  in 
which  the  question  whether  or  not  temporal  damage  could  be  said 
to  have  flowed  from  the  words  spoken,  had  been  discussed  with  so 
much  misplaced  subtlety.      In  the  third  place,  it  followed  also  that 

1  Skinner  at  p.  124. 

2  "  And  t'was  said  that  to  say  of  any  body  that  he  is  a  dishonest  man  is  not 
actionable,  but  to  publish  so,  or  to  put  it  up  upon  posts  is  actionable,"  Skin,  at  p.  124  ; 
S.C.  2  Show.  313. 

3  (1731)  Fitz-Gibbon  at  p.  254.  4(i76g)  2  Wils.  403. 

s "  1  repeat  it  that  I  wish  there  was  some  more  solemn  determination  that  the 
writing  and  publishing  anything  which  tends  to  make  a  man  ridiculous  or  infamous 
ought  to  be  punished,"  ibid  at  p.  404  per  Bathurst,  J. 

15  4  Taunt.  355.  7  Below  366.  8  Above  335. 

9 1  Ld.  Raym.  486  at  p.  490  per  Gould,  J. ;  cp.  Ratcliffe  v.  Evans  [1892]  2  Q.B. 
at  pp.  528-532  per  Bowen,  L.J. 


366  CRIME  AND  TORT 

the  courts  were  also  relieved  from  considering  whether  the  case 
fell  within  one  of  the  categories  of  words  actionable  per  se.  This 
meant  that  another  of  the  longest  and  most  unsatisfactory  series 
of  these  older  decisions  on  the  action  on  the  case  could  be  dis- 
regarded. For  these  three  reasons,  therefore,  the  invention  of 
the  separate  tort  of  libel  for  the  first  time  put  the  most  important 
branch  of  the  law  of  defamation  on  a  satisfactory  footing  ;  and  it 
cannot  be  doubted  that  the  principles  applied  to  this  tort  helped 
the  judges  to  improve  the  tort  of  slander,  by  enabling  them  to  dis- 
regard many  of  those  unprofitable  rules,  such  as  the  doctrine  of  the 
mitior  sensus,1  which  their  predecessors  had  laid  down  in  order  to 
discourage  the  action  on  the  case. 

At  the  same  time  this  improvement  had  been  effected  at  the 
expense  of  imposing  upon  the  law  the  unfortunate  distinction  be- 
tween the  torts  of  libel  and  slander.  At  the  latter  part  of  the 
seventeenth  century  this  may  well  have  seemed  not  too  high  a 
price  to  pay  for  the  rescue  of  the  tort  of  defamation  from  the 
wholly  unsatisfactory  condition  to  which  it  had  sunk.  But,  when 
the  law  had  been  reformed,  and  some  of  the  more  rational  rules  of 
libel  were  being  applied  to  slander ;  when  the  real  reasons  for  the 
decision  of  the  judges  to  treat  libel  as  an  independent  tort  had 
been  forgotten,  and  unsatisfying  a  priori  reasons  were  being  in- 
vented ; 2  the  absurdity  of  the  distinction  began  to  appear.  How 
completely  the  original  reason  for  the  establishment  of  the  distinc- 
tion had  been  forgotton  appears  from  Mansfield,  C.J.'s  judgment 
in  Thorley  v.  Kerry.'6  He  would  have  liked  to  assimilate  libel  to 
slander,  by  ruling  that  "no  action  could  be  maintained  for  written 
scandal  which  could  not  be  maintained  for  words  if  they  had  been 
spoken." 4  This  would  no  doubt  have  got  rid  of  the  separation  of 
the  two  torts ;  but  it  would  have  got  rid  of  it  at  the  expense  of 
undoing  most  of  the  good  effects  of  the  recognition  of  libel  as  a 
separate  tort,  and  of  throwing  the  law  back  into  the  state  in 
which  it  was  before  that  recognition  had  taken  place.  The 
converse  solution  would  have  been  infinitely  preferable.  Fortun- 
ately the  current  of  authority  was  too  strong  to  be  overruled  in 
this  way ; 5  and  so  it  may  be  said  that  the  case  affords  a  striking 

1  Above  355. 

3  See  Thorley  v.  Kerry  (1812)  4  Taunt,  at  p.  365  where  some  of  these  arguments 
are  exposed  by  Mansfield,  C.J. 

3  (1812)  4  Taunt.  355.  4  Ibid  at  p.  365. 

5 «'  These  are  the  arguments  which  prevail  on  my  mind  to  repudiate  the  distinc- 
tion between  written  and  spoken  scandal ;  but  that  distinction  has  been  established 
by  some  of  the  greatest  names  known  to  the  law,  Lord  Hardwicke,  Hale,  I  believe, 
Holt,  C.J.,  and  others  .  .  .  I  do  not  now  recapitulate  the  cases,  but  we  cannot,  in 
opposition  to  them,  venture  to  lay  down  at  this  day,  that  no  action  can  be  maintained 
for  any  words  written,  for  which  an  action  could  not  be  maintained  if  they  were 
spoken,"  4  Taunt,  at  p.  365. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  367 

illustration  of  the  salutary  principle  that  settled  rules  should  not 
be  lightly  overruled  on  a  priori  grounds. 

In  fact,  the  modern  torts  of  slander  and  libel  represent  two 
different  strata  of  legal  development  Slander  represents  the  tort 
developed  in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries  in  and 
through  the  action  on  the  case.  Libel  represents  the  tort  created 
by  the  judges  of  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,  in  order 
to  remedy  those  defects  of  the  tort  developed  in  the  earlier  period, 
which  had  been  caused  largely  by  the  efforts  of  the  judges  to  dis- 
courage the  action  on  the  case.  Their  action  put  the  tort  of  libel 
on  the  right  lines ;  and  if  ever  an  assimilation  between  the  two 
torts  is  effected  by  the  Legislature,  it  will  be  taken  as  the  model. 
At  the  same  time,  the  tort  developed  in  and  through  the  action  on 
the  case  in  the  earlier  period  has  influenced  in  many  ways  the 
later  development  of  the  law.  We  shall  now  see  that  some  of  the 
rules,  which  originated  in  the  action  on  the  case  for  defamation, 
were  applied  to  the  tort  of  libel ;  and,  similarly,  that  some  of  the 
rules  applicable  to  libel  as  a  crime  have  both  influenced,  and  been 
influenced  by,  the  development  of  the  torts  of  libel  and  slander. 

(3)  The  origin  of  some  of  the  essential  characteristics  of  the  torts 
of  libel  and  slander. 

During  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  we  can  see  the 
origins  of  some  of  the  essential  characteristics  of  the  tort  of  defam- 
ation. Many  of  them  originated  in  the  rules  applied  by  the 
common  law  courts  to  the  action  on  the  case,  and  were  applied 
both  to  slander  and  libel.  Some  of  them,  notably  the  rules  as  to 
the  innuendo  and  privilege,  were  applied  both  to  the  crime  and  to 
the  tort  of  defamation,  and  illustrate  the  manner  in  which  the  tort 
influenced  the  crime.  On  the  other  hand,  in  the  rule,  which  long 
prevailed,  that  the  statement  must  have  been  made  maliciously  we 
can  trace  one  way  in  which  the  crime  influenced  the  tort.  I  shall 
deal  with  these  rules  under  the  following  heads  : — (i)  the  words  or 
writing  must  be  defamatory,  and  they  must  be  proved  to  have 
been  spoken  or  written  in  the  manner  alleged  by  the  plaintiff; 
(ii)  they  must  be  proved  to  have  been  spoken  or  written  of  and 
concerning  the  plaintiff;  (iii)  they  must  have  been  published  to 
some  third  person  ;  (iv)  they  must  have  been  published  maliciously  ; 
and  (v)  they  must  not  admit  of  justification  nor  have  been  written 
or  spoken  on  a  privileged  occasion. 

(i)  The  words  or  writing  must  be  defamatory,  and  they  must 
be  proved  to  have  been  spoken  or  written  in  the  manner  alleged  by 
the  plaintiff. 

So  soon  as  the  courts  allowed  an  action  on  the  case  for  defama- 
tion, the  question,  what  statements  could  be  regarded  as  defamatory, 


368  CRIME  AND  TORT 

arose.  It  soon  became  clear  that  though,  as  to  some  statements, 
there  could  be  no  question,  as  to  others  the  context  and  circum- 
stances made  all  the  difference.  It  was  necessary,  therefore,  to 
lay  down  rules  as  to  the  manner  in  which  a  plaintiff,  who 
complained  of  one  of  these  ambiguous  statements,  must  frame  his 
pleading.  Partly  by  reason  of  the  growing  elaboration  of  the 
rules  of  pleading,  and  partly  by  reason  of  the  desire  of  the  judges 
to  discourage  these  actions,  the  rules  on  this  matter  were  strict. 
They  are  contained  in  the  mass  of  pleading  rules  which  grew  up 
round  the  "innuendo"  and  the  "colloquium." 

If  words  were  obviously  defamatory  of  the  plaintiff,  no  innuendo 
was  needed ;  and  if  they  were  obviously  not  defamatory,  an 
innuendo  could  not  make  them  actionable.  An  innuendo,  there- 
fore, could  only  be  of  use  where  the  statement  was  apparently 
defamatory,  but  where  the  person  or  thing  alluded  to  in  it  was  not 
described  with  sufficient  clearness.  It  could  not  add  to  the 
statement  any  additional  fact  needed  to  remedy  an  uncertainty  in 
the  person  defamed,  or  in  the  charge  made  against  that  person. 
It  could  only  indicate  with  greater  clearness  a  person  already 
mentioned,  or  a  charge  already  made.  These  rules  are  clearly 
illustrated  in  a  case  reported  by  Coke.1  Dealing  with  the  rule 
that  an  innuendo  could  only  indicate  with  greater  clearness  a 
person  already  mentioned,  he  says,  "If  one  says  without  any  pre- 
cedent communication  that  one  of  the  servants  of  J.  S.  (he  having 
many)  is  a  notorious  felon  or  traitor,  here,  for  the  uncertainty  of 
the  person,  no  action  lies ;  and  an  innuendo  cannot  make  it 
certain.  .  .  .  But  when  a  person  is  once  named  in  certain,  as  if 
two  speaking  together  of  J.  S.  one  says,  '  he  is  a  notorious  thief,' 
then  J.  S.  in  his  declaration  may  show  that  there  was  speech  of 
him  between  the  two,  and  that  one  said  !of  him,  '  he  (innuendo 
praedictum  J.  S.)  is  a  notorious  thief.'  For  the  office  of  an 
innuendo  is  to  contain  and  design  the  same  person  who  was 
named  in  certain  before,  and  in  effect  stands  in  lieu  of  a  praedict ', 
but  an  innuendo  cannot  make  a  person  certain  who  was  uncertain 
before."  Dealing  with  the  rule  that  it  could  only  indicate  with 
greater  clearness  a  charge  already  made,  he  says,  "  An  innuendo 
cannot  alter  the  matter  or  sense  of  the  words  themselves ;  and 
therefore  when  the  defendant  in  the  case  at  bar  said  of  the  plain- 
tiff, 'that  he  was  full  of  the  pox  (innuendo  the  French  pox),' 
this  innuendo  doth  not  do  its  proper  office,  for  it  endeavours  to 

1  James  v.  Rutlech  (1599)  4  Co.  Rep.  17  b  ;  cp.  Barham  v.  Nethersal  (1602)  ibid 
20a  ;  R.  v.  Griepe  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  259,  S.C.  2  Salk.  513  ;  cp.  March, 
Actions  for  Slaunder  (ed.  1647)  141 — "  the  office  of  an  innuendo  is  only  to  containe 
and  design  the  same  person  which  was  named  in  certain  before  ...  or  else  to  declare 
the  matter  or  sense  of  the  words  themselves  which  was  certainly  expressed  before." 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  369 

extend  the  general  words,  the  pox,  to  the  French  pox,  by 
imagination  of  an  intent  which  is  not  apparent  by  any  precedent 
words,  to  which  the  innuendo  should  refer." 

These  illustrations  indicate  the  function  of  the  colloquium.  As 
the  innuendo  could  only  clear  up  doubts  as  to  persons  or  matters 
already  referred  to,  it  was  necessary  to  set  out  all  these  persons 
and  matters  very  carefully  in  the  introductory  averments.1  These 
introductory  averments  were  known  as  the  colloquium,  and  this 
colloquium  must  contain  a  careful  narrative  of  all  the  circumstances 
which  were  necessary  to  be  stated,  in  order  to  prove  that  the 
words,  with  the  appropriate  innuendoes,  were  defamatory.  Un- 
less these  circumstances  ,were  stated  with  the  utmost  care,  it 
would  be  possible  to  arrest  judgment,  on  the  ground  that  the 
statement  and  the  innuendoes  gave  no  cause  of  action.-  It 
was  not  till  the  Common  Law  Procedure  Act  of  1852 3  that 
the  need  for  this  colloquium  was  removed,  and  that  plaintiffs, 
in  actions  for  libel  or  slander,  were  allowed  "to  aver  that  the 
words  or  matter  complained  of  were  used  in  a  defamatory 
sense,  specifying  such  defamatory  sense,  without  any  prefatory 
averment  to  show  how  such  words  or  matter  were  used  in  that 
sense." 

It  was  at  first  necessary  for  the  plaintiff  to  prove  that  the 
words  had  been  spoken  exactly  as  he  alleged  them.4  During  the 
eighteenth  century  this  strictness  was  somewhat  relaxed,5  but  not 
wholly  removed.6  And,  wherever  a  colloquium  was  necessary  to 
ground  the  action,  the  averments  in  the  colloquium  must  also  be 
strictly  proved.  Thus,  if  words  were  only  actionable  if  spoken 
of  the  plaintiff  in  his  trade,  there  must  be  a  colloquium  alleging 
this,  and  the  facts  there  set  out  must  be  proved.7 

1  "  That  in  all  cases  for  words,  where  there  is  anything  that  is  the  cause  or 
ground  of  the  action,  or  tends  necessarily  to  the  maintenance  of  it,  in  such  case  the 
action  will  not  lie,  without  that  thing  be  expressly  averred  to  be,  or  not  to  be,  as  the 
case  requireth,"  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  (ed.  1647)  142. 

2  Johnson  v.  Aylmer  (1606)  Cro.  Jac.  126  ;  Scutt  v.  Hawkins  (1623)  2  Rolle  Rep. 
243  ;  cp.  Dacy  v.  Clinch  (1661)  1  Sid.  52  for  a  case  in  which  a  motion  to  arrest  judg- 
ment on  this  ground  failed. 

3  15,  16  Victoria  c.  76  §  6r  ;  cp.  Watkin  v.  Hall  (1868)  L.R.  3  Q.B.  at  pp.  401- 
402  ;  Clerk  and  Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  567. 

4  "  Action  for  these  words :  '  Thou  (innuendo)  the  plaintiff  art  a  villainous  and  a 
murderous  quean  ;  for  thou  didst  murder  my  last  wife.'  The  defendant  pleaded  not 
guilty.  The  jury  found  that  the  defendant  spake  these  words  of  the  plaintiff  to  one 
Spinkfoot :  *  she  is  a  villainous  and  a  murderous  quean  ;  for  she  did  murder  my  last 
wife.'  Popham  and  Fenner  held  that  this  verdict  is  against  the  plaintiff;  for  they 
are  not  the  same  words  mentioned  in  the  declaration,"  Blisset  v.  Johnson  (1597) 
Cro.  Eliza.  503  ;  cp.  Sydenham  v.  May  (1616)  Hob.  180,  and  the  cases  cited  by 
Rolle,  Ab.  ii  718;  Hilsden  v.  Mercer  (1624)  Cro.  Jac.  677. 

5  See  Compagnon  v.  Martin  (1772)  2  W.  Bl.  790. 

6  See  Barnes  v.  Holloway  (1799)  8  T.R.  150. 

7  Savage  v.  Robery  (1699)  2  Salk.  694. 

VOL.  VIII. — 24 


370  CRIME  AND  TORT 

(ii)  The  words  or  writing  must  be  proved  to  have  been  spoken 
or  written  of  and  concerning  the  plaintiff. 

Just  as  the  law  required  strict  proof  that  the  statement  was 
defamatory,  and  that  it  had  been  written  or  spoken  as  alleged,  so 
it  required  strict  proof  that  it  was  written  or  spoken  of  and  con- 
cerning the  plaintiff.  Unless  it  was  alleged  in  the  plaintiff's 
declaration  that  the  statement  was  made  of  and  concerning  him, 
the  declaration  was  bad.  Thus,  in  the  case  of  Johnson  v.  Aylmer,1 
the  plaintiff  declared  that  the  defendant  spoke  and  published  the 
following  false  and  scandalous  words :  "  Mr.  Price,  you  do  my 
Lord  Burleigh  wrong,  that  you  do  not  apprehend  Jeremy  Johnson, 
innuendo  the  plaintiff,  for  a  felon,  and  seize  his  goods ;  for  he, 
innuendo  the  plaintiff,  hath  stolen  a  sheep  from  Wright  of  Rirsly, 
innuendo  John  Wright."  After  verdict  for  the  plaintiff,  it  was 
successfully  moved  in  arrest  of  judgment,  "that  the  words  are  too 
generally  laid  to  maintain  the  action ;  for  they  are  not  alleged  to 
be  spoken  of  the  plaintiff  in  the  writ  or  count ;  but  only  in 
reciting  the  words  he  saith,  innuendo  the  plaintiff;  and  the 
innuendo,  without  expressly  alleging  the  words  to  be  spoken  of 
the  plaintiff,  will  not  maintain  the  action."  This  principle  was 
rigidly  applied  in  later  law  both  to  actions  and  to  indictments,  as 
is  made  abundantly  clear  by  the  luminous  judgment  of  Fletcher- 
Moulton,  L.J.,  in  Jones  v.  Hulton}  But  the  decision  of  the 
majority  of  the  court  of  Appeal  and  the  House  of  Lords3  in  that 
case,  has,  in  effect,  placed  a  new  4  and  important  limitation  on  the 
generality  of  this  rule.  If  a  person  publishes  a  libellous  state- 
ment of  a  fictitious  person,  whom  he  christens  by  a  name  of  his 
own  choosing,  and  neither  knows  nor  cares  whether  or  not  his 
statement  can  be  taken  as  referring  to  an  existing  person  of  that 
name ;  and  if  in  fact  the  jury  is  satisfied  that  it  has  been  taken  to 
refer  to  an  existing  person ;  that  person  can  recover  damages. 

Recent  developments  in  modern  journalism  make  this  modi- 
fication of  the  strictness  of  the  old  principle  clearly  necessary ; 
and  the  technical  reasoning  by  which  the  law  has  been  thus 
modified  in  the  interests  of  substantial  justice,  is  a  good  instance 
of  the  flexibility  which  our  system  of  case  law  imparts  to  our 
legal  system.  In  effect,  it  is  based  on  an  analysis  of  the  nature 
of  the  intention  to  libel  the  plaintiff  which  the  law  requires.5     The 

1  (1606)  Cro.  Jac.  126. 

2  [1909]  2  K.B.  at  pp.  459-465  5  cp.  L.Q.R.  xxv  341-342. 

3  [1910]  A.C.  20. 

4  That  this  limitation  is  new  is  I  think  clear ;  on  this  I  agree  with  what  is  said 
L.Q.R.  xxvi  103-104,  "All  the  learning  and  subtlety  of  the  Lord  Justice  (Farwell, 
L.J.),  backed  by  the  agreement  of  the  noble  and  learned  Lords,  still  fail  to  convince 
us  that  this  is  not  very  new  law.  It  may  be  said,  however,  and  no  doubt  will  be,  that 
the  law  is  new  only  because  the  question  had  never  risen  in  such  a  form." 

6  [I9°9]  2  K.B.  at  pp.  480-482  per  Farwell,  L.J. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  371 

law  will  impute  intention  to  do  an  act,  not  only  if  the  defendant 
actually  meant  to  do  it,  but  also  if  he  acts  recklessly,  that  is 
without  any  care  whether  he  does  it  or  not.  Just  as  an  intention 
to  deceive  can  be  imputed,  both  where  a  person  makes  a  false 
statement  of  fact  with  knowledge  of  its  falsity,  and  also  where  he 
makes  such  a  statement  recklessly,  that  is  neither  knowing  nor 
caring  whether  it  be  true  or  false ;  so  an  intention  to  libel  the 
plaintiff  can  be  imputed  from  either  of  these  two  states  of  mind. 
"The  element  of  intention,  which  is  as  essential  to  an  action  for 
defamation  as  to  an  action  for  deceit,  can  be  proved  in  the  same 
way  in  both  actions."1 

(iii)  The  words  or  writings  must  have  been  published  to  some 
third  person. 

We  have  seen  that  this  rule  was  always  applied  to  the  action 
on  the  case,  because  it  followed  from  the  fact  that  the  damage  to 
the  person,  arising  from  the  defamatory  statement,  was  the  gist  of 
the  action.2  Therefore  the  plaintiff  must  always  allege  such  pub- 
lication in  his  declaration ; 3  and,  if  the  words  were  in  a  foreign 
language,  he  must  further  allege  that  they  were  understood  by 
those  who  heard  them.4  This  rule  as  to  the  necessity  of  publica- 
tion to  a  third  person  was  naturally  followed  in  the  case  of  libel  ; 
but  in  the  case  of  a  libel  written  in  a  foreign  language,  and  pub- 
lished to  the  world  at  large,  though  the  words  must  be  set  out, 
both  in  the  original  and  in  a  translated  form  in  the  plaintiff's 
declaration,5  the  allegation  that  they  were  understood  would  be 
obviously  unnecessary. 

(iv)  The  words  or  writings  must  have  been  published  maliciously. 

At  the  present  day  it  would  hardly  be  correct,  and  it  would 
certainly  be  misleading,  to  state  the  rule  in  this  form.  When  it 
is  said  that  the  words  or  writings  must  have  been  published 
maliciously,  all  that  is  meant  is  that  they  must  have  been  pub- 
lished without  just  cause  or  excuse.6  We  shall  see  that  this  was 
all  that  the  earlier  cases  upon  the  tort  of  defamation  meant ;  and 
we  have  seen  that  the  same  thing  is  true  of  the  crime  of  defama- 
tion.7 But,  when  it  became  customary  to  allege  malice  both  in 
declarations  in  civil  cases  and  in  indictments  in  criminal  cases,  it 
naturally   came   to   be   thought    that    malice   was    an   essential 

1  [1909]  2  K.B.  at  p.  481.  2  Vol.  v  207  ;  above  335. 

3  As  to  what  would  be  held  to  be  a  sufficient  allegation  of  publication,  see  Taylor 
v.  How  (1602)  Cro.  Eliza.  861 ;  Mors  v.  Thacker  (1677)  2  Lev.  193. 

*  Price  v.  Jenkings  (1602)  Cro.  Eliza.  865 ;  cp.  the  declaration  in  Jones  v.  Davers 
(1597)  ibid.  496. 

5  Zenobio  v.  Axtell  (1795)  6  T.R.  162  ;  1  Wms.  Saunders  242  n. 

6  Below  374-375-  7  Above  341-345- 


372  CRIME  AND  TORT 

ingredient  both  of  the  tort  and  crime.  Defamatory  statements, 
it  was  said,  must  have  been  published  maliciously.  It  was  how- 
ever admitted  that,  from  the  fact  that  a  false  and  defamatory 
statement  had  been  published  without  just  cause  or  excuse,  the 
law  implied  malice.  But  when  it  is  said  that  the  law  '  implies ' 
anything,  it  is  generally  the  case  that  the  thing  implied  is  not 
really  present.  Hence,  in  modern  times,  the  law  as  to  this  part 
of  the  subject  has  been  considerably  clarified,  by  the  recognition 
of  the  principle  that  malice  is  not  a  necessary  ingredient  either  in 
the  crime  or  in  the  tort  of  defamation ;  and  that  it  is  only  im- 
portant in  those  cases  in  which  the  defence  of  qualified  privilege 
is  set  up.  Thus  the  history  of  this  rule  is  the  history  of  its 
gradual  introduction  into,  and  final  elimination  from,  the  law. 

It  is  clear  from  the  conditions  under  which  the  action  on  the 
case  lay  that  malice  was  not  the  gist  of  the  action ;  and  this  was 
recognized  in  some  of  the  cases  decided  in  the  sixteenth  and  early 
seventeenth  centuries.  It  was  held  in  1 597  that  it  was  not  neces- 
sary in  an  action  on  the  case  to  allege  that  the  words  were  spoken 
"  malitiose."1  But,  in  the  earlier  case  of  Mercer  v.  Sparks?  we 
can  see  a  hint  of  the  manner  in  which  the  idea  that  malice  is  a 
necessary  ingredient  in  the  tort  will  be  introduced.  In  that  case 
it  was  held  that  it  was  no  error  not  to  allege  that  the  words  were 
spoken  maliciously,  "  because  the  words  themselves  were  malicious 
and  slanderous."  Clearly  this  comes  very  near  to  the  rule  that 
malice  is  implied.  It  is  not  therefore  surprising  to  find  that  in  other 
cases  it  is  laid  down  that  the  malice  or  intention  to  slander  was  of 
the  essence  of  the  cause  of  action.3  Moreover,  no  very  clear  distinc- 
tion was  as  yet  drawn  between  the  malice  which  the  law  implies 
from  the  speaking  of  slanderous  words,  and  the  express  malice  which 
will  rebut  a  defence  of  qualified  privilege,  because,  as  we  shall  see, 
the  conception  of  qualified  privilege  had  not  as  yet  been  attained.4 

In  1652  Rolle,  C.J.,  restated  the  rule  that,  in  an  action  for 
slander,  there  was  no  need  to  allege  that  scandalous  words  were 
spoken  malitiose ;  but  he  added  that,  in  an  indictment,  such  an 
allegation  must  be  made,  because  that  was  the  usual  form.5  In 
this  statement  we  can  see  an  indication  of  the  manner  in  which  the 
idea  that  malice  was  an  essential  ingredient  in  the  tort  of  defama- 
tion was  introduced  into  the  law.     We  have  seen  that,  when  the 

1  Anon.  Moore  459 — "  Auter  error  assigne  quia  ne  fuit  alledge  que  les  parols  fuerunt 
paries  malitiose,  et  uncore  auxi  bone  en  action  sur  le  cas  pour  parols." 

2  (1586)  Owen  51. 

3  This  point  comes  out  clearly  enough  in  Brook  v.  Montague  (1606)  Cro.  Jac.  90, 
and  in  the  ruling  of  Wray,  C.J.,  in  the  case  cited  ibid  at  p.  91. 

4  Below  377. 

6  "  And  he  said  that  in  an  endictment  a  thing  must  be  expressed  to  be  done  lalso  et 
malitiose,  because  that  is  the  usual  form,  but  in  a  declaration  those  words  are  not 
necessary,"  Anon.  Style  392. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  373 

criminal  jurisdiction  formerly  exercised  by  the  Star  Chamber  in 
libel  cases  was  taken  over  by  the  courts  of  common  law,  the  allega- 
tion that  the  statement  was  made  maliciously  was  always  made.1 
It  is  true  that  the  judges  tried  to  neutralize  the  effect  of  this  con- 
ception of  the  crime,  by  holding  that  the  legal  effect  of  the  words 
published,  and  therefore  their  malice,  were  matters  of  law  for  the 
court,  and  not  matters  of  fact  for  the  jury.2  But  they  obviously 
thought  that  malice  must  be  regarded  as  a  necessary  ingredient  of 
the  crime.  As  we  have  seen,  they  would  have  greatly  strengthened 
their  position  at  the  expense  of  the  jury,  if  they  could  have  ruled 
that  malice  was  not  a  necessary  ingredient ;  for  in  that  case  it 
would  have  been  quite  clear  that  all  the  jury  had  to  find  was  the 
publication  of  a  writing  bearing  the  meaning  alleged  by  the 
prosecution.  No  room  would  have  been  left  for  the  contention 
that,  as  malice  was  the  gist  of  the  offence,  the  jury  must  be  con- 
vinced that  the  publication  was  malicious,  before  they  found  the 
accused  guilty  of  libel,  just  as  they  must  be  convinced  that  a 
homicide  was  malicious,  before  they  found  the  accused  guilty  of 
murder.3  It  is  not  surprising  that  it  became  more  and  more  usual 
for  plaintiffs  who  were  suing  in  tort  for  libel  or  slander,  to  allege 
malice ;  and  that,  in  spite  of  the  earlier  precedents  to  the  contrary, 
it  gradually  came  to  be  thought  that  malice  was  as  essential 
an  element  of  the  tort  as  of  the  crime.  In  a  case  of  1632, 
reported  by  March,  the  plaintiff  had  alleged  that  the  words  were 
spoken  "falso  et  malitiose,"  and  the  jury  found  that  they  were 
spoken  "falso  et  injuriose."  Judgment  was  given  against  the 
plaintiff,  because  the  jury  did  not  find  malice — "  for  if  the  words  were 
not  spoken  maliciously,  no  action  will  lie."  *  This  statement  of  the 
law  no  doubt  confirmed  the  existing  practice  of  always  alleging 
malice.  Thus  in  1737  it  was  said  "that  words  are  always  laid  to 
be  spoken  falso  et  malitiose,  and  that  therefore  any  evidence  prov- 
ing them  not  to  be  so  ought  to  be  admitted."  To  this  proposition 
the  court  seems  to  have  assented,  for,  "  it  was  agreed  that  malice 
is  the  gist  of  this  action  and  that  therefore  evidence  proving  the 
manner  and  occasion  of  speaking  the  words  to  show  that  they  were 
not  spoken  with  malice  has  always  been  admitted. " 5  And  the 
law  was  stated  in  the  same  way  by  Comyns6  and  Blackstone.7 

1  Above  341-342.  2  Above  343-345.  3  Above  342-343. 

4  Actions  for  Slaunder  (ed.  1647)  *2* — he  concluded  from  this  case  that  if  the 
declaration  did  not  state  "  that  the  words  were  spoken  malitiose  as  well  as  /also  the 
action  will  not  lie." 

5  Smith  v.  Richardson,  Willes  at  p.  24. 

6  "  The  declaration  must  show  a  malicious  intent  in  the  defendant,"  Digest,  Action 
on  the  Case  for  Defamation  G.  5  ;  note  however  that,  having  made  this  general  state- 
ment, Comyns  at  once  qualifies  it  by  the  admission  that  "  it  is  sufficient  to  say  falso 
dixit  without  malitiose." 

7  "  Words  of  heat  and  passion,  as  to  call  a  man  rogue  and  rascal,  if  productive  of 
no  ill  consequence,  and  not  of  any  of  the  dangerous  species  before  mentioned,  are  not 


374  CRIME  AND  TORT 

But,  in  the  first  quarter  of  the  nineteenth  century,  it  began  to 
be  perceived  that  malice  was  not  an  essential  ingredient  in  either 
the  crime  or  the  tort  of  defamation.  This  new  view  of  the  law 
rested  in  substance  on  a  distinction  between  what  was  called 
"  legal  "  malice  or  malice  implied  by  law,  and  "  actual  "  malice.  As 
long  ago  as  1 7 1 3  this  distinction  had  been  recognized  by  Parker, 
C.J.,  who  had  pointed  out  that  the  former  variety  of  malice  meant 
nothing  more  than  that  the  thing,  said  to  be  maliciously  done,  was 
done  without  just  cause  or  excuse.1  But  it  was  not  till  the  be- 
ginning of  the  nineteenth  century  that  this  doctrine  was  applied  to 
defamation,  because  it  was  not  till  then  that  the  disturbing  effects 
of  the  controversy,  as  to  the  rights  of  juries  in  cases  of  libel,  had 
been  quieted  by  Fox's  Libel  Act.2  As  the  result  of  that  Act,  it 
was  possible  to  approach  the  question  as  a  pure  matter  of  law ;  for, 
however  libel  was  defined,  the  jury  could  now  return  a  general 
verdict  on  the  whole  question.  The  manner  in  which  this  new 
view  of  the  law  was  put  forward  and  reconciled  with  the  older 
view,  will  appear  from  the  following  cases  :  In  1823,  in  the  case 
of  R.  v.  Harvey,  Holroyd,  J.,  said  that,  "It  is  not  necessary  to 
aver  in  such  an  indictment  any  direct  malice,  because  the  doing  of 
such  an  act  without  any  excuse  is  indictable.  ...  If  the  matter 
published  was  in  itself  mischievous  to  the  public,  the  very  act  of 
publishing  is  prima  facie  evidence  to  show  that  it  was  done  malo 
animo  ;  for  when  a  publication  having  such  an  injurious  tendency 
is  proved,  it  is  intended  to  have  been  done  with  a  malicious  inten- 
tion ;  because  the  principle  of  law  is  that  a  party  must  always  be 
taken  to  intend  those  things  and  those  effects  which  naturally  grow 
out  of  the  thing  done."3  In  1825,  in  the  case  of  Bromagev. 
Prosser?  this  rule  was   applied  to  actions  for   tort ;    and  it  was 

actionable  :  neither  are  words  spoken  in  a  friendly  manner,  as  by  way  of  advice,  ad- 
monition, or  concern,  without  any  tincture  or  circumstance  of  ill  will ;  for  in  both 
these  cases  they  are  not  maliciously  spoken,  which  is  part  of  the  definition  of  slander. 
.  .  .  What  was  said  with  regard  to  words  spoken,  will  also  hold  in  every  particular 
with  regard  to  libels  by  writing  or  printing,  and  the  civil  actions  consequent  thereupon," 
Bl.  Comm.  iii  125-126;  dealing  with  the  criminal  law,  he  defines  libels  as  *'  malicious 
defamations  of  any  person,  and  especially  a  magistrate,  made  public  by  either  printing 
writing  signs  or  pictures  in  order  to  provoke  him  to  wrath,  or  expose  him  to  public 
hatred  contempt  and  ridicule,"  ibid  iv  150. 

1  "  Malice  in  common  acceptation  is  a  desire  of  revenge,  or  a  settled  anger 
against  a  particular  person.  .  .  .  This  is  by  the  vulgar  use  of  the  words  in  English. 
But  (it)  is  not  the  legal  sense  taking  them  as  law  terms.  ...  In  short  malice  and 
maliciously  I  take  to  be  terms  of  law  which  in  the  legal  sense  always  exclude  a  just 
cause.  So  in  case  of  murder,  the  statutes  take  away  clergy  in  case  of  wilful  murder  of 
malice  prepense,  when  wilful  stands  in  opposition  to  accidental,  and  of  malice  to 
cases  of  reasonable  provocation,  such  as  might  move  an  honest  and  good  man  ;  and 
the  Court  and  not  the  jury  have  ever  determined  of  malice.  And  the  question  has 
always  been  with  or  without  cause  or  excuse,  and  therefore  that  which  is  only  malice 
implied  by  law,  perhaps  would  be  expressed  more  intelligibly,  at  least  more  familiarly, 
if  it  were  called  malice  in  a  legal  sense,"  Jones  v.  Givin  (1713)  Gilb.  Cas.  at 
pp.  190-193. 

3  Above  345.  s  2  B,  and  C.  at  pp.  266-267.  4  4  B.  and  C.  247. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  375 

clearly  laid  down  that,  except  as  an  answer  to  the  defence  of 
privilege,  the  allegation  of  malice  was  unnecessary.  "  Malice,"  it 
was  said,  "  in  common  acceptation  means  ill  will  against  a  person, 
but  in  its  legal  sense  it  means  a  wrongful  act  done  intentionally 
without  just  cause  or  excuse."1  Except  when  malice  is  alleged 
as  an  answer  to  the  defence  of  privilege,  the  term  is  used  in  its 
legal  sense.  Hence  it  is  not  necessary  to  aver  it,  as  the  law  im- 
plies it  from  the  fact  that  a  defamatory  statement  has  been  made.2 
But,  in  the  course  of  the  nineteenth  century,  it  was  admitted  that 
the  general  rules  of  pleading  were  the  same  in  criminal  and  in 
civil  cases.3  These  two  cases  were  therefore  held,  in  R.  v. 
Munslow*  in  1895,  to  show  that  malice  was  not  an  essential 
ingredient,  either  in  the  crime  or  the  tort  of  defamation. 

We  have  seen  that,  in  the  seventeenth  century,  the  influence 
of  the  criminal  law  had  helped  to  establish  the  view  that  malice 
was  an  essential  ingredient  in  the  tort  of  defamation.5  The 
judgment  in  R.  v.  Munslow  shows  that,  in  the  nineteenth  century, 
the  influence  of  the  law  of  tort  helped  to  overthrow  this  view,  and 
to  establish  the  rule  that  malice  is  not  an  essential  ingredient  in 
either  the  crime  or  the  tort  of  defamation,  and  that  it  only  becomes 
important  when  a  plea  of  privilege  is  set  up.  To  the  origins  of 
the  conception  of  privilege  we  must  now  turn. 

(v)  The  words  or  writing  must  not  admit  of  justification  nor 
have  been  spoken  or  written  on  a  privileged  occasion. 

We  have  seen  that  to  an  action  for  the  tort  of  defamation  a 
plea  of  truth  was  always  a  defence.6  This  plea  is  known  as  a  plea 
of  justification  ;  and  the  same  strict  principles  were  applied  to  the 
construction  of  such  a  plea  as  were  applied  to  the  plaintiff's 
declaration.  Thus,  in  the  case  of  Johns  v.  Gittings,7  the  plea  was 
held  bad,  partly  upon  the  ground  that  the  defendant  had  not  fully 
justified  the  words  which  he  was  alleged  to  have  used ;  and  it  is 
still  the  law  that  a  plea  of  justification  is  bad,  unless  it  establishes 

1  At  p.  255  per  Bayley,  J. 

3  "  If  I  traduce  a  man,  whether  I  know  him  or  not,  and  whether  I  intend  to  do 
him  an  injury  or  not,  I  apprehend  the  law  considers  it  as  done  of  malice,  because  it  is 
wrongful  and  intentional.  It  equally  works  an  injury,  whether  I  meant  to  produce  an 
injury  or  not,  and  if  1  had  no  legal  excuse  for  the  slander,  why  is  he  not  to  have  a 
remedy  against  me  for  the  injury  it  produces  ?  And  I  apprehend  the  law  recognises 
the  distinction  between  these  two  descriptions  of  malice,  malice  in  fact  and  malice  in 
law,  in  actions  of  slander.  In  an  ordinary  action  for  words,  it  is  sufficient  to  charge 
that  the  defendant  spoke  them  falsely.  .  .  .  But  in  actions  for  such  slander  as  is 
prima  facie  excusable  on  account  of  the  cause  of  speaking  or  writing  it,  as  in  the  case 
of  servants'  characters  .  .  .  malice  in  fact  must  be  proved  by  the  plaintiff,"  4  B.  and 
C.  at  p.  255. 

3  Heymann  v.  R.  (1873)  L.R.  8  Q.B.  at  p.  105  per  Blackburn,  J. 

*  [1895]  1  Q.B.  758.  5  Above  373.  •  Vol.  v  207. 

7  (1590)  Cro.  Eliza.  239  ;  cp.  Hilsden  v.  Mercer  (1624)  Cro.  Jac.  677  ;  1  Wins. 
Sanders,  244  n. 


376  CRIME  AND  TORT 

that  the  statement  "was  true  as  a  whole  and  in  every  material 
part  thereof."1  In  addition  to  this  narrower  sense  of  the  term 
justification,  it  is  sometimes  used  in  a  larger  sense  to  mean  a 
defence  which  otherwise  justifies,  i.e.  renders  legal,  the  making  of 
a  defamatory  statement.  In  other  words,  it  covers  the  defence  of 
privilege ;  for  privilege,  like  truth,  is  a  defence  to  an  action  for 
libel  or  slander ;  and,  unlike  truth,  it  is  also  a  defence  to  a 
criminal  prosecution.2 

During  this  period  the  law  as  to  privilege  was  meagre,  and  the 
modern  distinction  between  absolute  and  qualified  privilege  had 
not  arisen.  Most  of  the  cases  are  cases  of  what  we  should  now 
call  absolute  privilege.  The  earlier  cases  all  turn  upon  documents 
written  with  a  view  to,  or  in  the  course  of,  judicial  proceedings,  or 
upon  words  spoken  by  persons  concerned  in  litigation.  Thus,  it 
was  held  in  1 5  69,  that  to  sue  out  a  writ  for  forgery  of  deeds  could 
not  be  made  the  basis  of  an  action  for  scandalum  magnatum  ; 3 
and  the  same  rule  was  applied  in  1585  to  matter  alleged  in 
articles  of  the  peace,  exhibited  to  the  justices.4  It  was  settled,  by 
the  first  quarter  of  the  seventeenth  century,  that  no  action  lay 
against  judges,  witnesses,  or  counsel  for  defamatory  statements 
made  in  the  conduct  of  litigation ; 5  and  it  was  settled  by  the 
case  of  Lake  v.  King  in  i668,G  after  considerable  debate  and  con- 
flict of  judicial  opinion,  that  a  similar  rule  must  be  applied  to 
documents,  circulated  to  the  members  of  a  committee  of  the  House 
of  Commons,  and  dealing  with  the  matters  which  that  committee 
was  appointed  to  consider.7  This  case  settled,  in  substance,  that 
documents  connected  with  Parliamentary  proceedings,  and  pub- 
lished to  members  of  Parliament,  had  the  same  privilege  as  had 
already  been  accorded  to  judicial  proceedings.  A  little  later  it 
was  settled  there  was  no  privilege  for  those  who  published 
documents  connected  with  these  proceedings  to  the  world  at 
large. 8 

1  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  261.  2  Kenny,  Criminal  Law,  309-310. 

3  Lord  Beauchamp  v.  Croft  Dyer  285a. 

4  Cutler  v.  Dixon  4  Co.  Rep.  14b — "  If  actions  should  be  permitted  in  such  cases, 
those  who  have  just  cause  for  complaint,  would  not  dare  to  complain  for  fear  of  infinite 
vexation." 

5  Brook  v.  Montague  (1606)  Cro.  Jac.  go  ;  Weston  v.  Dobniet  (1618)  ibid  432  ; 
Harding  v.  Bodman  (1618)  Hutton  11 ;  Ram  v.  Lamley  (1633)  ibid  113  ;  cp.  Floyd 
v.  Barker  (1608)  12  Co.  Rep.  23  where  the  judicial  immunity  from  all  actions  arising 
out  of  things  done  in  a  judicial  capacity  is  laid  down  in  very  wide  terms;  for  the 
history  of  these  rules  see  vol.  vi  234-240. 

H 1  Wms.  Sanders  131. 

7  Kelyng,  C.J.,  held  that,  though  the  exhibiting  of  the  petition  was  lawful,  "  the 
printing  of  it  was  a  publication  to  all  the  world,  which  is  not  lawful,"  ibid  at  p.  132  ; 
but,  "  after  this  case  had  depended  twelve  terms,  now  this  term  judgment  was  given 
for  the  defendant  by  Hale,  Chief  Justice,  Twysden,  and  Rainsford,  upon  this  point, 
namely,  that  it  was  the  order  and  course  of  proceedings  in  Parliament  to  print  and 
deliver  copies  etc.,  whereof  they  ought  to  take  judicial  notice,"  ibid  at  p.  133. 

8  R.  v.  Salisbury  (1699)  *  Ld.  Raym.  341. 


DEFAMATION  AS  A  TORT  377 

The  idea  that  there  could  be  any  privilege  for  those  who  pub- 
lished true  reports  of  judicial  or  Parliamentry  proceedings  had  not 
as  yet  arisen.1  In  fact  it  could  not  arise,  till  the  courts  had 
arrived  at  the  modern  distinction  between  absolute  and  qualified 
privilege,  and  had  ascertained  the  true  meaning  of  the  latter  kind 
of  privilege ;  for  the  privilege  accorded  to  these  reports 
at  the  present  day  is  essentially  qualified  privilege,  in  as  much  as 
it  can  be  rebutted,  if  the  report  can  be  shown  to  be  garbled  or 
unfair.2  During  this  period,  we  can  only  see  faint  traces  of  the 
ideas  which  underlie  the  conception  of  qualified  privilege  ;  and  the 
notion  that  privilege  could  be  divided  into  these  two  classes  had 
not  as  yet  arisen.  In  a  case  of  the  year  1 597,  it  was  ruled  that 
defamatory  words  spoken  by  the  defendant  of  the  plaintiff,  in 
order  to  advise  a  third  person  upon  a  matter  in  which  he  had  an 
interest,  were  not  actionable.3  We  can  see  here  the  germ  of 
the  idea  which  will  cover  most  of  the  cases  of  qualified  privilege 
in  later  law ;  and  it  would  seem  that  the  law  had  not  advanced 
very  far  beyond  this  stage  when  Blackstone  wrote.4  In  a  case  of 
the  year  1 606,  we  can  see  the  germ  of  the  idea  that  a  statement, 
prima  facie  privileged,  will  lose  its  privilege  if  spoken  with 
malice.6  But  this  was  said  of  a  statement  which  would,  at  the 
present  day,  be  absolutely  privileged,  so  that  it  is  clear  that  the 
courts  had  as  yet  no  idea  of  the  modern  distinction.  No  doubt 
the  very  wide  terms  in  which  the  privilege  accorded  to  judicial 
and  Parliamentary  proceedings  was  being  laid  down  by  the  courts, 
helped  to  give  rise  to  the  modern  conception  of  absolute  privilege. 
But  probably  the  uncertainty  which,  as  we  have  seen,6  long  pre- 
vailed as  to  the  part  played  by  malice  in  the  tort  and  crime  of 
defamation,  helped  to  retard  the  recognition  of  the  conception  of 
qualified  privilege. 

1  See  Wason  v.  Walter  (1868)  L.R.  4  Q.B.  at  pp.  93-94 per  Cockburn,  C.J. ;  and 
ep.  Curry  v.  Walter  (1796)  1  B.  and  P.  525. 

2 "  It  is  to  be  observed  that  the  analogy-  between  the  case  of  reports  of  pro- 
ceedings of  courts  of  justice  and  those  of  proceedings  in  Parliament  being  complete, 
all  the  limitations  placed  on  the  one  to  prevent  injustice  to  individuals  will  necessarily 
attach  on  the  other  :  a  garbled  or  partial  report,  or  of  detached  parts  of  proceedings, 
published  with  intent  to  injure  individuals,  will  equally  be  disentitled  to  protection," 
Wason  v.  Walter  at  p.  94. 

3  The  plaintiff  alleged  that  he  was  a  merchant,  and  that  the  defendant,  to  discredit 
him,  said  to  D,  "  Doth  Vanspike  (the  plaintiff)  owe  you  any  money  "  ?  and  that  on  D 
saying  that  he  did,  the  defendant  said,  "  you  had  best  call  for  it ;  take  heed  how  you 
trust  him  "  ;  judgment  was  given  for  the  defendant,  "  for  it  is  not  any  slander  to  the 
plaintiff,  but  good  counsel  to  D,"  Vanspike  v.  Cleyson,  Cro.  Eliza.  541. 

4  Bl.  Comm.  iii  125,  cited  above  373  n.  7  ;  but  it  was  just  about  this  period  that 
the  modern  law  was  beginning  to  be  developed  by  Lord  Mansfield,  see  Weatherston 
v.  Hawkins  (1786)  1  T.R.  no. 

5  Brook  v.  Montague  Cro.  Jac.  90 — -"  if  he  (counsel)  give  in  evidence  anything  not 
material  to  the  issue,  which  is  scandalous,  he  ought  to  aver  it  to  be  true,  otherwise  he 
is  punishable ;  for  it  shall  be  intended  as  spoken  maliciously  and  without  cause  "  ;  and 
the  law  so  stated  by  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  (ed.  1647)  1 19-120. 

6  Above  345,  372-375- 


378  CRIME  AND  TORT 

In  the  law  of  defamation,  as  in  many  other  branches  of  the 
common  law,  the  outlines  of  the  modern  law  emerged  during  the 
sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries.  But,  owing  principally  to  the 
great  changes  effected  by  the  introduction  of  printing,  and  to  some 
extent  to  the  desire  of  the  common  law  courts  to  expand  their 
jurisdiction,  this  branch  of  the  law  is,  perhaps,  more  distinctly 
than  any  other,  the  creation  of  these  two  centuries.  At  the  be- 
ginning of  the  period  the  ecclesiastical  courts  still  retained  the 
lion's  share  of  this  jurisdiction  ;  and  it  was  only  in  cases  involving 
the  exercise  of  the  statutory  jurisdiction  over  the  defamation  of 
magnates,  that  the  common  law  regularly  interfered.  At  the 
end  of  this  period  the  criminal  law  of  defamation,  which  had  been 
created  by  the  Star  Chamber,  had  been  taken  over  by  the  common 
law ;  and  the  torts  of  libel  and  slander  had  been  established  on 
substantially  their  modern  basis.  The  law  as  thus  settled  has  not 
been  found  to  be  wholly  satisfactory  in  later  periods  in  the  history 
of  the  law.  In  the  eighteenth  century,  political  developments  ne- 
cessitated important  changes  in  the  criminal  law  ;  and  the  division 
of  the  tort  of  defamation  into  libel  and  slander — a  division  due 
historically  to  the  need  for  finding  some  remedy  for  the  mis- 
takes made  by  the  common  law  in  the  initial  stages  of  the  develop- 
ment of  the  tort — still  disfigures  the  law.  But  the  definition  of 
the  tort  of  libel  was  on  the  whole  satisfactory ;  and  it  has  formed 
a  good  starting  point  for  the  development  of,  and  a  sufficient  frame- 
work, for  the  many  detailed  rules  which  the  modern  expansion  of 
literature  and  journalism  has  necessitated.  If  the  rules  appli- 
cable to  libel  were  applied  to  all  kinds  of  defamation,  and  the 
fact  that  the  defamation  was  oral,  was  only  allowed  to  weigh  in 
considering  the  measure  of  damages,  no  serious  complaint  could 
be  made  against  our  modern  law. 


§  3.  Conspiracy,  Malicious  Prosecution,  and  Maintenance 

Conspiracy  and  Malicious  Prosecution 

We  have  seen  that  two  divergent  streams  of  doctrine  have 
gone  to  the  making  of  the  law  of  conspiracy,  (i)  Statutes  of  the 
thirteenth  century  had  provided  a  writ  of  conspiracy,  which  lay 
against  two  or  more  persons  who  had  combined  to  indict  or  appeal 
another  of  felony,  if  that  other  had  been  acquitted  by  verdict  of 
the  jury.1  In  addition,  the  mediaeval  common  law  had  developed 
an  action  on  the  case  in  the  nature  of  conspiracy,  which  was 
generally  brought  for  a  combination  to  defraud  the  plaintiff  by  the 

J  Vol.  iii  402-405. 


THE  MODERN  CRIME  OF  CONSPIRACY   379 

fraudulent  use  of  the  machinery  of  the  courts ;  and  the  damage, 
and  not  the  conspiracy,  being  the  gist  of  this,  as  of  other  actions 
on  the  case,  it  differed  from  the  statutory  writ  in  that  it  lay  against 
one  defendant  only.1  (ii)  The  court  of  Star  Chamber  had  enlarged 
the  scope  of  the  offence  of  conspiracy.  It  punished  criminally, 
not  only  conspiracies  to  abuse  the  process  of  the  courts,  but  also 
conspiracies  to  commit  any  wrongful  act ; 2  and  we  have  seen  that 
the  jurisdiction  which  it  assumed  in  these  cases,  tended  to  shade 
off  into  the  very  salutary  jurisdiction  which  it  exercised  over 
attempts  to  commit  crimes.3  Moreover,  though  it  treated  these 
conspiracies  as  criminal  offences,  it  adopted,  somewhat  illogically, 
the  rule  applied  by  the  common  law  to  the  action  on  the  case,  and 
punished  a  single  person  who  had  made  a  false  accusation.4 

When  the  common  law  courts  took  over  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
Star  Chamber,  they  found  it  necessary  to  construct  a  law  of  con- 
spiracy on  these  foundations.  The  result  of  their  efforts  can  be 
summed  up  as  follows :  Firstly,  they  adopted  the  wide  definition 
of  conspiracy  which  had  grown  up  in  the  court  of  Star  Chamber, 
and  so  created  the  modern  crime  of  conspiracy ;  but,  as  the  gist 
of  the  crime  was  the  conspiracy,  they  held  that  it  could  not  be 
committed  by  a  single  person.  Secondly,  from  the  statutory  writ 
of  conspiracy  and  the  action  on  the  case,  they  developed  the  tort 
of  malicious  prosecution.  Thirdly,  at  a  later  date  it  came  to  be 
thought  that  acts  which  would  amount  to  the  crime  of  conspiracy, 
would  also  give  rise  to  an  action  in  tort  for  conspiracy  at  the  suit 
of  an  individual  damaged  thereby ;  and,  as  the  gist  of  this  action 
was  not  the  conspiracy,  but  the  resulting  damage,  it  followed  that 
it  would  lie  against  a  single  defendant.  But  whether  in  such  a 
case  the  cause  of  action  is  the  conspiracy,  or  whether  it  is  not 
rather  the  unlawful  acts  done  in  pursuance  thereof — whether,  in 
other  words,  there  is  any  such  thing  as  a  separate  tort  of  conspiracy, 
is  a  controverted  question  which  has  given  rise  to  much  difference 
of  opinion. 

With  the  history  of  these  developments  I  propose  to  deal 
under  the  following  heads  :  (i)  The  modern  crime  of  conspiracy  ; 
(2)  Malicious  prosecution  ;  and  (3)  The  modern  tort  of  conspiracy. 

(1)   The  modern  crime  of  conspiracy . 

The  modern  crime  of  conspiracy  is  almost  entirely  the  result 
of  the  manner  in  which  conspiracy  was  treated  by  the  court  of 
Star  Chamber.  Almost  the  only  idea  which  it  has  borrowed  from 
the  common  law  is  the  rule,  taken  from  the  statutory  writ  of 
conspiracy,  that  the  crime  (like  the  crime  of  riot)  cannot  be  com- 
mitted by  one  person,  though  the  other  persons  need  not  be  specified, 

1  Vol.  iii  405-407.  2  Vol.  v  204-205, 

3  Ibid  201,  203,  204.  4  Ibid  204. 


380  CRIME  AND  TORT 

and  may  indeed  be  unknown.1  The  other  two  essential  features 
of  the  crime — (i)  the  fact  that  the  gist  of  the  offence  is  the  con- 
spiracy and  not  acts  done  in  pursuance  thereof,  and  (ii)  the  fact 
that  the  crime  is  committed  if  persons  conspire  to  commit  any 
unlawful  act,  or  any  lawful  act  by  unlawful  means — are  derived 
ultimately  from  the  practice  of  the  Star  Chamber.2  But  these  two 
essential  features  were  developed  by  the  common  law  courts  after 
the  Restoration ;  and  it  is  of  the  beginnings  of  this  development 
that  I  must  speak  at  this  point. 

(i)  When  it  is  said  that  the  gist  of  the  offence  is  the  conspiracy, 
what  is  meant  is  that  the  offence  consists,  not  in  the  illegal  acts 
done  in  pursuance  thereof,  but  in  the  act  of  agreement  or  combina- 
tion for  these  purposes.  But  there  must  always  have  been  an 
overt  act  of  agreement  or  combination,  so  that  a  mere  uncom- 
municated  intention  to  conspire  is  not  a  conspiracy.  Just  as  in  the 
case  of  high  treason,  where  the  offence  is  the  intention  to  kill  the 
king,  so  in  conspiracy,  where  the  offence  is  the  fact  of  agreement 3 
— in  neither  case  can  the  offence  be  committed  unless  an  overt  act 
manifesting  an  intention  to  kill,  or  an  agreement  to  do  the  unlawful 
act,  be  proved.  It  is  clear  from  Coke's  statement  in  The  Poulterers' 
Case4"  that  the  common  law  has  always  required  proof  of  a  "co- 
adunation,  confederacy  or  false  alliance  "  ; 5  and  there  is  no  reason 
to  think  that  the  law  of  the  Star  Chamber  was  otherwise.  This 
is  assumed  in  the  later  cases  ;  and  that  this  assumption  was 
correct  was  laid  down  by  Willes,  J.,  and  assented  to  by  the  House 
of  Lords  in  1868,  in  a  statement  which  was  noteworthy,  not  for 
its  novelty,  but  for  the  clearness  with  which  it  defined  the  meaning 
of  both  of  the  two  essential  features  of  the  crime.6     Of  the  second 

1  R.  v.  Starling  (1664)  1  Sid.  174,  cited  below  n.  3  ;  R.  v.  Kinnersley  (1719) 
1  Str.  193 ;  Kenny,  op.  cit.  288 ;  Winfield,  Hist,  of  Conspiracy  59-65 ;  for  the 
rule  applicable  to  the  statutory  writ  see  vol.  iii  405  ;  and  for  the  rule  applicable  to  riot 
see  above  324. 

2  Vol.  v  204-205. 

3  "  Nepoit  estre  conspiracy  sans  ascun  overt  act  de  plusors,"  R.  v.  Starling  (1664) 
1  Sid.  at  p.  174 ;  cp.  R.  v.  Best  (1705)  1  Salk.  174  ;  R.  v.  Kinnersley  (1719)  1  Str.  at 

P-  195- 

4(i6n)  9  Co.  Rep.  55b. 

5  "  The  usual  commission  of  oyer  and  terminer  gives  power  to  the  commissioners 
to  enquire,  etc.,  dc  omnibus  coadunationibus  confctderationibus  et  jalsis  alligantiis ; 
and  coadttnatio  is  a  uniting  of  themselves  together,  confcederatio  a  combination 
amongst  them,  and  falsa  alligantia  is  a  false  binding  each  to  the  other,  by  bond  or 
promise,  to  execute  some  unlawful  act :  in  these  cases  before  the  unlawful  act  executed 
the  law  punishes  the  coadunation,  confederacy,  or  false  alliance  to  the  end  to  prevent 
the  unlawful  act,"  ibid  at  ff.  56b,  57a. 

6  "  A  conspiracy  consists  not  merely  in  the  intention  of  two  or  more,  but  in  the  agree- 
ment of  two  or  more  to  do  an  unlawful  act,  or  to  do  a  lawful  act  by  unlawful  means.  So 
long  as  such  a  design  rests  in  intention  only  it  is  not  indictable.  When  two  agree 
to  carry  it  into  effect,  the  very  plot  is  an  act  in  itself,  and  the  act  of  each  of  the  parties, 
promise  against  promise,  actus  contra  actum,  capable  of  being  enforced  if  lawful, 
punishable  if  for  a  criminal  object  or  for  the  use  of  criminal  means,"  Mulcahy  v.  R, 
(1868)  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  at  p.  317. 


THE  MODERN  CRIME  OF  CONSPIRACY   381 

of  these  essential  features,  emphasized  in  the  statement  of  Willes 
J.,  I  must  now  say  a  few  words. 

(ii)  It  is  well  established  law  at  the  present  day  that  the 
crime  is  committed  by  an  agreement  to  do  an  unlawful  act,  or  to 
do  a  lawful  act  by  unlawful  means.  If  the  act  agreed  to  be  done 
is  a  crime  or  a  tort — at  any  rate  a  malicious  tort,1  or  if  means  are 
to  be  adopted  to  secure  a  lawful  object,  which  involve  the  com- 
mission of  a  crime  or  a  tort,  there  is  no  difficulty.  The  chief 
difficulty,  to  which  the  definition  of  the  crime  has  given  rise, 
consists  in  the  fact  that  an  act  may  be  sufficiently  unlawful  to 
render  an  agreement  to  do  it  a  criminal  conspiracy,  though  it 
cannot  be  brought  under  any  of  the  recognized  categories  of  crime 
or  tort  That  this  was  so,  was  clearly  recognized  by  the  common 
law  courts  after  the  Restoration.  In  addition  to  conspiracies  to 
indict  maliciously,  which  fell  under  the  statutory  writ  of  con- 
spiracy,2 and  to  do  acts  which  amounted  to  a  crime  or  a  tort,3 
conspiracies  to  do  acts,  which  were  neither  crimes  nor  torts,  were 
held  to  be  indictable.  Thus,  the  brewers  of  London  were  held  to 
be  guilty  of  conspiracy,  because  they  had  conspired  to  carry  on 
their  trade  in  such  a  way  that  the  revenue  was  defrauded ; 4  and 
the  journeyman  tailors  of  Cambridge  were  likewise  held  to  have 
committed  this  offence,  because  they  had  conspired  to  raise  their 
wages.5  In  the  last  mentioned  case  the  court  expressly  laid  it 
down  that  "a  conspiracy  of  any  kind  is  illegal,  although  the 
matter  about  which  they  conspired  might  have  been  lawful  for 
them  or  any  of  them  to  do,  if  they  had  not  conspired  to  do  it,  as 
appears  in  the  case  of  The  Tubwomen  v.  The  Brewers  of  London."  6 
These  cases  were  followed  in  later  law  ; "  and,  as  Professor  Kenny 
has  pointed  out,  they  have  made  it  possible  "  for  judges  to  treat 
all  combinations  to  effect  any  purpose  which  happens  to  be  dis- 
tasteful to  them  as  indictable  crimes,  by  declaring  this  purpose  to 
be  'unlawful.'"8 

1  Kenny,  op.  cit.  289. 

2  R.  v.  Kimberty  (1662)  1  Lev.  62 ;  R.  v.  Best  (1705)  1  Salk.  (174). 

3  R.  v.  Twisleton  and  others  (1668)  1  Sid.  387 — taking  a  daughter  and  marrying  her 
without  the  father's  assent;  R.  v.  Grey  and  others  (1682)  9  S.T.  127 — conspiracy 
to  debauch  a  woman ;  R.  v.  Thorp  (1697)  5  Mod.  221 — taking  a  son  and  heir  and 
seducing  him  to  contract  a  disgraceful  marriage ;  R.  v.  Orbell  (1704)  6  Mod.  42,  12 
Mod.  499 — conspiracy  to  cheat  by  running  slackly  in  a  race ;  see  also  Winfield, 
op.  cit.  112-115. 

4  R.  v.  Starling  (1664)  1  Sid.  174. 

5  R.  v.  Journeymen  Taylors  of  Cambridge  (1721)  8  Mod.  n. 

6  8  Mod.  at  pp.  n-12;  cp.  the  argument  in  R.  v.  Thorp  (1697)  5  Mod.  at  p.  224— 
"  that  which  is  lawful  for  one  man  to  do  may  be  made  unlawful  to  be  done  by  con- 
spiracies :  for  instance,  it  is  lawful  for  any  brewer  to  brew  small  beer,  but  if  several 
shall  conspire  together  to  brew  no  strong,  but  all  small  beer,  on  purpose  to  defraud 
the  king  of  his  duties,  such  conspiracy  is  unlawful.  And  so  it  was  held  in  Sir  Samuel 
Sterling's  case,  who,  because  he  could  not  farm  the  excise,  did  confederate  with 
several  brewers  to  brew  small  beer  only." 

7  Kenny,  op.  cit.  289-290.  8  Ibid  291. 


382  CRIME  AND  TORT 

There  can  be  little  doubt  that  this  wide  definition  of  the  crime 
of  conspiracy  originates  in  the  criminal  equity  administered  in  the 
Star  Chamber.  We  have  seen  that  Hudson  says  that  the  Court 
acted  as  "  the  curious  eye  of  the  state  and  the  king's  Council, 
prying  into  the  inconveniences  and  mischiefs  which  abound  in 
the  Commonwealth,"  1  and  that,  "  by  the  arm  of  sovereignty  it 
punisheth  errors  creeping  into  the  Commonwealth,  which  other- 
wise might  prove  dangerous  and  infectious  diseases,  or  it  giveth 
life  to  the  execution  of  laws,  or  the  performance  of  such  things  as 
are  necessary  in  the  Commonwealth,  yea,  although  no  positive 
law  or  continued  custom  of  the  common  law  giveth  warrant  to  it." 2 
Clearly,  it  is  these  ideas  which  the  common  law  adopted,  when  they 
held  that  conspiracies  to  do  acts,  which  were  neither  crimes  nor 
torts,  were  indictable.  These  acts  were  contrary  to  public  policy, 
and  therefore  a  conspiracy  to  effect  them  must  be  treated  as  a 
crime.  This  idea  came  naturally  to  the  court  of  Star  Chamber, 
because  it  was  intimately  allied  to  the  Council — the  governing 
body  in  the  state  in  the  sixteenth  and  early  seventeenth  centuries. 
It  came  equally  naturally  to  the  common  law  courts,  when  the 
Star  Chamber  had  been  abolished,  and  when  the  common  law 
had  made  good  its  claim  to  be  the  supreme  law  in  the  state. 

It  was  inevitable  that  it  should  be  through  the  law  of  con- 
spiracy that  the  common  law  should  apply  these  ideas.  In  the 
first  place,  it  was  a  far  more  elastic  crime  than  the  older  and  more 
precisely  defined  offences  known  to  the  earlier  common  law.  In 
the  second  place,  the  law  as  to  the  punishment  of  attempts  to 
commit  crimes  was  still  rudimentary,  till  it  was  put  on  a  more 
satisfactory  basis  by  the  adoption  of  the  Star  Chamber  doctrines 
on  this  matter.3  A  criminal  conspiracy,  as  defined  by  the  Star 
Chamber,  and  an  attempt  to  commit  a  crime,  are  closely  allied ; 4 
and  an  alternative  method  of  dealing  with  such  offences  was  as 
valuable  to  the  common  law  courts  as  to  the  Star  Chamber.  In 
the  third  place,  a  combination  of  any  kind,  unless  it  is  very  care- 
fully regulated  by  the  state,  must  always  (in  spite  of  the  a  priori 
views  of  political  speculators)  be  dangerous  to  the  authority  of  the 
state,  and  the  regular  administration  of  its  law ; 5  and  a  fortiori  a 
combination  formed  to  effect  illegal  or  questionable  purposes. 
"  Leagues  of  the  subjects  of  one  and  the  same  Commonwealth," 
says  Hobbes,  "  where  every  one  may  obtain  his  right  by  means  of 
the  Sovereign  Power,  are  unnecessary  to  the  maintaining  of  peace 
and  justice,  and  (in  case  the  designe  of  them  be  evill  or  unknown 

1  Star  Chamber  126,  cited  vol.  i  504. 

2  Star  Chamber  107,  cited  vol.  i  504. 

:)  Vol.  v  201.  4  Ibid  203,  204. 

6  Vol.  iii  478-479. 


THE  MODERN  CRIME  OF  CONSPIRACY   383 

to  the  Commonwealth)  unlawfull.  For  all  uniting  of  strength  by 
private  men,  is  if  for  evill  intent  unjust ;  if  for  intent  unknown, 
dangerous  to  the  Publique,  and  unjustly  concealed."1  And 
Burke  agreed  with  him — "liberty,"  he  said,  "when  men  act  in 
bodies  is  power."  2  This  danger,  inherent  in  combinations,  was 
increased  by  the  inadequacy  of  the  police  system  of  the  seven- 
teenth and  eighteenth  centuries ; 3  and,  as  we  can  see  more  clearly 
than  the  politicians  of  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  it 
is  not  removed  by  a  police  system  sufficient  to  guard  the  state 
against  ordinary  criminals.4  This  is,  in  fact,  the  true  reason  why 
such  a  crime  as  conspiracy  is  as  essential  a  part  of  the  criminal 
law  in  the  twentieth  as  in  the  sixteenth  century. 

In  fact,  just  as  in  the  law  of  contract  the  courts  used  the  doc- 
trine of  public  policy  to  control  certain  of  the  activities  of  the 
citizen,5  so  in  the  criminal  law  it  used  this  wide  conception  of 
conspiracy  for  the  same  purpose.  And  just  as  in  the  law  of  con- 
tract there  is  a  legitimate  use  for  this  doctrine,  so  there  is  a 
legitimate  use  for  it  in  the  criminal  law.  In  both  cases  it  is  used 
legitimately  to  strike  at  practices  and  courses  of  conduct  which  are 
contrary  to  the  established  principles  of  the  common  law,  and  are 
obviously  dangerous  to  the  state.  In  both  cases,  because  it  is  an 
elastic  doctrine,  it  gives  the  law  a  power  of  so  developing  its 
principles  that  they  are  kept  in  touch  with  the  needs  and  ideas  of 
the  age.  But,  in  the  criminal  law,  just  as  in  the  law  of  contract, 
it  may  be  used  illegitimately,  and  may  become  merely  another 
name  for  political  expediency ;  and  there  is  obviously  a  greater 
danger  that  it  will  be  thus  used  illegitimately  in  the  criminal  law ; 
for  in  this  branch  of  the  law  its  action  is  more  direct,  and  can  be 
made  to  cover  a  much  wider  ground.  There  is  therefore  more 
danger  that  it  will  be  used  to  give  effect  to  the  political  prejudices 
of  the  judges ;  and,  as  we  can  see  from  the  legal  history  of  the 
seventeenth  century,6  and  from  our  own  experience,  to  put  judges 
in  a  position  in  which  they  can  hardly  avoid  adjudicating  upon 
political  questions,  is  detrimental,  both  to  the  impartial  considera- 
tion of  questions  of  legal  principle,  and  to  their  own  authority. 

Just  as  it  is  in  relation  to  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade  that 
the  doctrine  of  public  policy  in  contract  law  has  received  its  most 

1  Leviathan  Pt.  ii  c.  22  p.  122. 

a  French  Revolution,  9. 

5  "  In  days  when  our  police  system  was  ineffective,  the  law  felt  itself  dangerously 
threatened  by  any  concert  among  evil  doers ;  and  consequently,  in  the  seventeenth 
and  eighteenth  centuries,  indictments  against  conspirators  were  held  good  very 
readily,"  Kenny,  op.  cit.  290-291. 

4  "  It  is  not  a  set  number  that  makes  the  Assembly  unlawfull,  but  such  a  number 
as  the  present  officers  are  not  able  to  suppresse  and  bring  to  justice,"  Hobbes, 
Leviathan  Pt.  ii  c.  22  p.  123. 

5  Above  54-56.  «  Vol.  v  350-352,  421-422. 


384  CRIME  AND  TORT 

important  application,1  so  it  is  in  relation  to  the  freedom  of  em- 
ployers and  workmen  to  use  their  capital  and  labour  as  they  please, 
that,  in  our  own  times,  the  criminal  law  of  conspiracy  has  received 
its  most  striking  applications.  The  repeal  of  the  combination  laws, 
and  of  nearly  all  the  other  laws  which  regulated  commerce  and 
industry,  under  the  influence  of  the  doctrine  of  laissez-faire,  gave 
both  to  employers  and  workmen  a  large  liberty,  which  they  used 
or  attempted  to  use  in  a  manner  destructive  of  liberty.  And  just 
as  the  large  powers  allowed  by  law  to  landowners,  and  other  owners 
of  property,  necessitated  the  creation  of  a  rule  against  perpetuities, 
to  prevent  that  liberty  being  used  to  its  own  destruction,2  so  the 
large  liberty  allowed  to  employers  and  workmen,  necessitated  large 
developments  in  the  law  of  conspiracy,  to  guard  against  attempted 
infractions  of  individual  liberty  thereby  rendered  possible.  But  the 
history  of  the  manner  in  which  the  common  law  attempted,  by  the 
application  of  the  law  of  conspiracy,  to  safeguard  this  liberty,  and  of 
the  very  different  solutions  of  the  problem  from  time  to  time  enforced 
by  the  Legislature,  belongs  to  the  legal  history  of  the  nineteenth 
and  twentieth  centuries.  Here  we  need  only  note  that,  though  the 
technical  weapon  was  different,  the  policy  pursued  by  the  common 
law  was  the  same  as  that  which  has  resulted  in  the  rules  as  to  the 
invalidity  of  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade,  and  in  the  rules  against 
perpetuities.  In  all  these  cases  the  policy  aimed  at  was  the  removal 
of  the  danger  of  arbitrary  restraints  on  freedom — on  the  freedom 
of  contract,  on  the  freedom  of  alienation,  and  on  the  freedom  to 
dispose  of  one's  capital  or  labour  at  one's  will.  In  all,  except  the 
last  and  the  most  important  of  these  aims,  the  ideas  of  the  common 
law  have  triumphed,  to  the  manifest  advantage  of  the  community. 
Whether  or  not  it  would  not  have  been  equally  to  the  advantage 
of  the  community,  if,  in  this  last  case  also,  the  common  law  had 
triumphed,  will  be  one  of  the  most  interesting  problems  awaiting 
the  students  of  the  political,  economic,  and  legal  history  of  our  own 
times. 

The  growth  of  this  crime  of  conspiracy  naturally  gave  rise  to 
the  problem  whether  or  not  a  person  injured  by  an  indictable  con- 
spiracy had  a  right  of  action  in  tort,  and,  if  so,  what  was  the  nature 
of  that  right  of  action.  We  shall  see  that  this  problem  did  not 
become  acute  in  this  period ;  but,  as  some  of  the  considerations 
relevant  to  its  discussion  do  emerge,  I  must  say  a  few  words  about 
it.  But,  before  it  can  be  profitably  discussed,  I  must  deal  with  the 
later  history  of  the  statutory  writ  of  conspiracy,  and  the  supplemen- 
tary action  on  the  case,  and  show  how,  from  these  two  remedies, 
the  modern  torts  of  malicious  prosecution,  and  malicious  abuse  of 
the  process  of  the  courts,  have  emerged. 

1  Above  56-62.  2  Vol.  vii  193-194. 


MALICIOUS  PROSECUTION  385 

(2)  Malicious  prosecution. 

It  was  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth  centuries  that  the 
definition  of  the  competence  of  the  statutory  writ  of  conspiracy, 
and  the  development  of  the  action  on  the  case  founded  upon  it,  1 
gave  rise  to  the  torts  of  malicious  prosecution,  and  malicious  abuse  I 
of  the  process  of  the  courts.  Though,  as  we  have  seen,  there  are 
a  few  hints  in  the  mediaeval  period  that  the  action  on  the  case  j 
might  have  been  used  to  redress  conspiracies  other  than  those  con- 
nected with  the  malicious  use  of  legal  process,1  this  line  of  develop- 
ment was  not  pursued.  For  remedies  against  other  kinds  of 
conspiracies  litigants  applied  to  the  court  of  Star  Chamber,2  with 
the  result  that  the  common  law  remedies  never  developed  in  this 
direction.  They  did  however  develop,  during  this  period,  in  a 
manner  which  is  closely  parallel  to  other  developments  of  common 
law  remedies.  In  the  first  place,  the  criminal  element  in  the 
statutory  writ  of  conspiracy  was  tending  to  evaporate  during  the 
mediaeval  period  ;  and  this,  as  we  have  seen,  is  precisely  what  was 
happening  in  the  case  of  the  writ  of  trespass.3  It  disappeared 
entirely  during  this  period,  because  its  place  was  taken  by  the 
much  wider  conception  of  conspiracy,  which  was  being  developed  ! 
from  the  principles  applied  in  the  court  of  Star  Chamber.  In  the 
second  place,  the  action  on  the  case,  which,  even  in  the  mediaeval 
period,  had  begun  to  be  used  to  supplement  the  defects  of  the 
statutory  writ,  practically  superseded  it  during  this  period ;  and  | 
this,  as  we  have  seen,  is  precisely  what  was  happening  in  the  case 
of  such  writs  as  debt  and  detinue.4  The  history  of  these  develop- 
ments, and  of  the  modern  torts  which  resulted  from  them,  I  must 
now  trace. 

In  one  respect  the  statutory  writ  of  conspiracy,  and  the  action  on 
the  case,  resembled  one  another — it  is  fairly  certain  that  the  plaintiff 
must  prove  that  the  proceedings  taken  against  him  were  both  false 
and  malicious,  and  that  they  terminated  in  his  favour.5     But  we 


1  Vol.  iii  406.  2  Vol.  v  205. 

3  Vol.  iii  318,  370.  *  Ibid  351,  428  seqq. ;  vol.  vii  402,  413-414. 

s  Vol.  iii  403,  405  ;  Staunford,  P.C.  Bk.  iii  c  11 ;  Payne  v.  Porter  (1619)  Cro.  jac. 
490  ;  March,  Actions  for  Slaunder  (ed.  1647)  130- 131,  citing  a  ruling  of  Tanfield,  J., 
in  1606,  thus  sums  up  the  law  of  his  time:  "  A  conspiracy  nor  an  action  in  nature  of 
a  conspiracy  will  not  lie  if  the  plaintiff  be  not  legitimo  modo  acquietatus  ;  but  if  one 
procure  another  to  be  indicted  arrested  and  imprisoned  falso  et  malitiose,  he  shall  have 
an  action  on  the  case  for  the  slander  and  vexation  though  that  he  be  never  acquitted 
(i.e.  acquitted  by  verdict) ;  and  he  said  that  the  like  action  upon  the  case  had  been  ad- 
judged to  lie  well,  though  that  the  plaintiff  were  never  acquitted ;  and  the  justices 
relied  much  upon  the  words  falso  et  malitiose  ;  and  after,  judgment  was  given  for  the 
plaintiff.  Thus  you  may  see  that  when  a  man  is  falsely  and  maliciously  procured  to 
be  indicted,  if  he  be  acquitted,  a  writ  of  conspiracy  or  action  on  the  case  in  nature  of 
a  conspiracy,  as  the  case  shall  be,  will  he,  and  though  he  be  not  acquitted,  yet  an 
action  upon  the  case  will  he  for  the  slander  and  vexation  ";  for  a  full  discussion  of 
this  point  see  Winfield,  op.  cit  83  seqq. 

VOL.   VIII.— 25 


386  CRIME  AND  TORT 

'lhave  seen  that  in  other  respects  they  were  very  different.1     The 

taiain  points  of  difference  can  be  summarized  as  follows :  Firstly, 

the  statutory  writ  applied  only  to  a  conspiracy  to  indict  or  appeal 

a  man  of  felony ;  but  the  action  on  the  case  applied  to  conspiracies 

jto  accuse  a  man  of  other  offences,  or  to  harass  him  by  the  malicious 

labuse  of  the  process  of  the  courts.     Secondly,  a  plaintiff  could 

'only  use  the  statutory  writ  if  he  had  been  acquitted  by  verdict. 

If  he  had  escaped  in  any  other  way,  e.g.  by  reason  of  a  defective 

indictment,  he  could  not  make  use  of  the  writ.     But  the  action  on 

the  case  was  not  fenced  about  by  any  such  restrictions.     Thirdly, 

t  as  the  gist  of  the  offence  covered  by  the  statutory  writ  was  the 

I  conspiracy,  it  could  not  be  brought  against  one  person  only ;  but, 

jas  the  gist  of  the  action  on  the  case  was  the  resulting  damage,  it 

]  could  be  brought  against  one  person  only.     We  shall  now  see  that 

it  was  the  development  of  these  three  characteristics  of  the  action 

on  the  case  which  eliminated  the  element  of  conspiracy,  and  created, 

sfrom   these   common    law  remedies    for   conspiracy,   the   tort   of 

j  malicious  prosecution,  and  other  torts  analogous  thereto. 

(i)  The  extension  of  the  action  on  the  case  to  cover  all  kinds 
of  malicious  conspiracies  to  injure  another  by  an  abuse  of  the 
process  of  the  courts,  involved  (a)  its  extension  to  a  conspiracy 
to  accuse  another  of  the  more  serious  offence  of  treason ;  (b)  its 
•  extension  to  a  conspiracy  to  accuse  another  of  some  less  serious 
misdemeanour ;  and  (c)  its  extension  to  a  conspiracy  to  injure 
\  another  by  other  abuses  of  process. 

(a)  The  question  whether  the  statutory  writ  lay  against 
persons  who  had  maliciously  conspired  to  indict  another  of 
treason,  had  not,  as  we  have  seen,  been  raised  in  the  Middle 
Ages.2  It  seems  to  have  been  raised  for  the  first  time  in  1 614, 
in  the  case  of  Lovet  v.  Faulkner?  In  that  case  Coke,  C.J.,  and 
the  whole  court  were  of  opinion  that  no  such  action  would  lie. 
Coke  pointed  out  that  there  was  no  precedent  for  such  an  action — 
"  all  the  precedents  are  pro  felonia "  ; 4  and  both  Coke  and  the 
court  evidently  considered  that  it  would  be  dangerous  to  the 
safety  of  the  state  to  make  a  precedent,  as  it  might  discourage 
persons  from  giving  information  of  treasonable  plots.5     No  actual 

1  Vol.  iii  406-407. 

3  On  this  matter  see  generally  Winfield,  op.  cit.  58-59  ;  cp.  vol.  iii  405. 

3  2  Bulstr.  270. 

4  "  I  never  yet  did  know  in  case  of  high  treason,  and  for  the  prosecution  thereof 
against  one,  any  writ  of  conspiracy  ever  brought.  There  is  no  case  in  the  law  for 
this,  but  all  the  presidents  are  pro  felonia ;  high  treason  concerns  the  person  of  the 
king ;  and  there  is  no  book  in  law  to  warrant  the  bringing  of  such  an  action  for  a 
prosecution  pro  proditione,"  ibid  at  p.  271. 

5  "  Haughton  and  Dodderidge  et  tota  Curia,  every  one  by  his  oath  of  allegiance 
is  bound  to  discover  treason,  and  to  have  one  punished  for  this,  by  an  action  upon  the 
case  in  the  nature  of  a  writ  of  conspiracy,  to  be  brought  against  him  ;  this  should  be 
very  hard,"  ibid. 


MALICIOUS  PROSECUTION  387 

decision  was  given.  But  it  is  clear  that  this  opinion  was  based 
mainly  on  political  grounds;  and  in  1623,  the  court,  after  a  long 
argument,  held,  in  the  case  of  Smith  v.  Crans/iaw,1  that  an 
action  would  lie.  The  court  pointed  out  that,  though  a  person 
might  be  obliged  to  reveal  treason,  he  was  certainly  not  bound  to 
accuse  others  of  treason  falsely  and  maliciously ;  that  it  would  be 
most  unreasonable  if  a  person  falsely  and  maliciously  accused  had 
no  remedy;  and  that  there  was  no  warrant  in  Edward  I.'s  statute 
for  confining  even  the  statutory  writ  to  false  and  malicious  accusa- 
tions of  felony.  Dodderidge,  J.,  cited  a  case  in  which  such  an 
action  had  been  successfully  brought ; 2  and,  as  Dr.  Winfield  has 
pointed  out,  the  Star  Chamber  punished  persons  who  made  such 
accusations  falsely  and  maliciously.3 

(&)  We  have  seen  that  the  rule  that  the  action  on  the  case 
could  be  used  to  remedy  a  conspiracy  to  accuse  another  of 
trespass,  or  other  offence  under  the  degree  of  felony,  had  been 
recognized  in  the  Middle  Ages.4  It  was  accepted  as  well-estab- 
lished law  in  this  period.  Thus,  in  the  case  of  Marham  v. 
Pescod?  an  allegation  that  the  plaintiff  was  "  legitime  acquietatus," 
without  saying  "de  felonia,"  was  held  to  be  sufficient  in  an  action 
on  the  case,  though  it  would  not  have  been  sufficient  in  proceed- 
ings on  the  statutory  writ ;  and  it  was  held  in  Carlion  v.  Mill 6 
that  the  action  lay  for  a  malicious  citation  before  the  ecclesiastical 
courts.  But  it  would  seem  that,  at  the  latter  part  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  the  courts  were  beginning  to  think  that  some 
limitation  should  be  put  on  the  scope  of  the  action.  It  was 
suggested  in  one  case  that  it  should  be  limited  to  cases  where  the 
indictment  "  contains  matter  of  imputation  and  slander  as  well  as 
crime";7  and  it  would  seem  that  this  had  given  rise  to  the  opinion 
that  the  action  would  not  lie  for  the  malicious  preferment  of  any 
indictment  for  trespass  8 — an  opinion  clearly  contrary  to  the  older 
cases. 

1  W.  Jones,  93  ;  S.C.  2  Rolle  Rep.  258. 

a  "  Come  fuit  a  ore  in  un  case  de  Cambridgeshire,  lou  un  conspire  ove  auter  pur 
indicter  J.S.  de  treason,  que  ilsfont,  apres  l'un  confesse  que  le  auter  ad  suborne  luy, 
et  que  ils  font  sur  ceo  malice,  sur  que  il  auxi  confesse  ceo,  et  conspiracy  port  sur  ceo 
vers  eux,  et  l'un  est  a  cest  jour  imprison  pur  ceo,"  2  Rolle  Rep.  at  p.  260. 

3  Op.  cit.  59  n.  7.  *  Vo'.  iii  406. 

5  (1603)  Cro.  Jac.  130  ;  cp.  Bell  v.  Fox  and  Gamble  (1610)  Cro.  Jac  270 — a  case 
on  the  statutory  writ. 

6  (1633)  Cro.  Car.  291. 

7  Thus  in  Henley  v.  Burstal  (1669)  Th.  Raym.  180  Serjt.  Maynard  argued  that, 
"  when  the  indictment  is  preferred  maliciously,  and  such  indictment  contains  matter 
of  imputation  and  slander  as  well  as  crime  ;  then  the  action  lies  ;  but  otherwise  when 
the  indictment  contains  crime  without  slander,  as  forcible  entry  etc.  ...  and  of  that 
opinion  was  all  the  court";  see  also  Low  v.  Beardmore  (1665)  ibid  135,  and 
Chamberlain  v.  Prescot  (1639)  there  cited,  where  this  view  was  apparently  upheld  by 
the  Exchequer  Chamber. 

8  "  The  opinion  of  all  the  judges  in  the  case  of  Sir  Andrew  HetiUv  and  Dr. 
Burstall  Th.   Raym.  180  was,  that  no  action  will  lie  for  falsely  and  maliciously 


388  CRIME  AND  TORT 

(c)  There  are  several  cases  in  which  the  action  on  the  case 
was  brought  for  miscellaneous  abuses  of  legal  proceedings.  Thus, 
it  was  held  that  the  malicious  suing  out  of  a  writ  of  fieri  facias,1 
or  capias  ad  satisfaciandum,2  was  a  good  ground  for  an  action  on 
the  case ;  and,  in  the  case  in  which  the  former  point  was  decided, 
it  was  laid  down  generally  that,  "  if  a  man  sue  me  in  a  proper 
court,  yet  if  his  suit  be  utterly  without  ground  of  truth,  and 
certainly  known  to  himself,  I  may  have  an  action  of  the  case 
against  him  for  the  undue  vexation  and  damage  that  he  putteth 
me  unto  by  his  ill  practice,  though  the  suit  itself  be  legal,  and  I 
cannot  complain  of  it  as  it  is  a  suit."  3  It  is  thus  clear  that  the 
action  was  being  used  to  cover  many  miscellaneous  cases  of 
malicious  abuse  of  process.  But  it  would  seem  that  the  nature 
of  the  wrongs  thus  redressed  was  as  yet  not  nicely  distinguished. 
In  particular,  the  case  of  Steer  v.  Scoble  ^  shows  that  no  clear  line 
was  as  yet  drawn  between  the  acts  which  will  constitute  the  tort 
of  malicious  prosecution,  and  those  which  will  constitute  the  tort 
of  false  imprisonment. 

(ii)  These  extensions  of  the  sphere  of  the  action  on  the  case 
necessarily  helped  to  emphasize  the  rule  that  it  was  not  confined 
to  cases  where  the  plaintiff  had  been  acquitted  by  verdict ;  because, 
obviously,  in  many  of  these  cases  in  which  the  action  was  held  to 
lie  such  acquittal  was  not  possible.  There  are  many  cases  illus- 
trating the  application  and  the  extension  of  this  rule  in  this  period. 
In  Sydenham  v.  Keilaway 5  in  1 574  it  was  held  that,  where  the  jury 
had  ignored  the  indictment,  though  the  statutory  writ  would  not 
lie,  the  action  on  the  case  would ;  and  in  1 6 1 9  the  court  of  Ex- 
chequer Chamber  decided  the  same  point  in  the  same  way.6  In 
Francis  Throgmortoris  Case  in  1 597 7  the  court  held  that  the 
action  did  not  lie,  if  the  plaintiff  escaped,  because  the  court,  be- 
fore which  the  indictment  was  tried,  had  no  jurisdiction ;  but  in 
Atwoodv.  Monger*  in  1653  it  was  held  that  the  action  would  lie 

procuring  a  man  to  be  indicted  of  a  trespass.  He  said  that  he  remembered  that  they 
were  of  such  opinion,  and  denied  the  case  of  7  Hen.  4.  31  (7  Hy.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  15, 
vol.  iii  405  and  n.  3).  But  to  that  he  answered,  that  though  he  had  a  great  regard  to 
what  the  judges  then  said,  for  the  Court  was  then  composed  of  very  knowing  men, 
yet  that  opinion  was  not  judicial,  for  such  matter  was  not  then  in  question,"  Savile  v. 
Roberts  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  379  per  Holt,  C.J. ;  and  at  p.  380  he  said  that 
Bridgman,  C.J.,  "  was  against  all  such  actions." 

1  Waterer  v.  Freeman  (1618)  Hob.  205,  266. 

2  Steer  v.  Scoble  (1624)  Cro.  Jac.  667 ;  Daw  v.  Swaine  (1669)  1  Sid.  424. 

3  Hob.  at  p.  267. 

4  (1624)  Cro.  Jac.  667 ;  cp.  Barker  v.  Braham  (1779)  2  W.  Bl.  867,  where,  in  a 
case  similar  to  Steer  v.  Scoble,  the  action  was  brought  for  false  imprisonment ;  the 
modern  distinction  is  most  clearly  explained  by  Willes,  J.,  in  Austin  v.  Dowling 
(1870)  L.R.  5  CP.  at  pp.  538-54I- 

5  Cro.  Jac.  7 — there  reported  ex  relatione  Popham,  C.J.  ;  see  generally  on  this 
topic  Winfield,  Present  Law  of  Abuse  of  Legal  Procedure  181-187. 

6  Payne  v.  Porter,  Cro.  Jac.  490.  7  Cro.  Eliza  563. 

8  Style  378  ;  Rolle,  C.J.,  at  p.  379  said,  "  an  action  upon  the  case  lies  for  bringing 
an  appeal  against  one  in  the  Common  Pleas,  though  it  be  coram  non  judice,  by  reason 


MALICIOUS  PROSECUTION  389 

in  these  circumstances.  Tn  two  cases,  one  of  Charles  I.'s1  and 
the  other  of  Charles  I  I.'s  reigns,2  a  distinction  was  drawn  between 
the  rule  laid  down  in  the  last  cited  case,  and  cases  where  the  in- 
dictment was  bad  on  the  face  of  it.  In  the  latter  class  of  cases  it 
was  held  an  action  on  the  case  would  not  lie,  so  that  in  these 
cases  the  rule  applicable  to  the  statutory  writ  and  to  the  action  on 
the  case  was  the  same.  Possibly  this  distinction  was  drawn  with  a 
view  of  discouraging  these  actions  ;  but  it  was  clearly  a  distinction 
without  a  difference,  and  we  shall  see  that  it  was  overruled 3  both 
by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  Savile  v.  Roberts*  and  by  Parker,  C.J.,  in  Jones 
v.  Giving  Thus  the  rule  that  the  action  on  the  case  both  for 
malicious  indictment  and  for  malicious  abuse  of  legal  process  would 
lie,  if  the  proceedings  had  in  any  way  terminated  in  the  plaintiff's 
favour,  was  established.  The  necessity  for  showing  an  acquittal  by 
verdict  was  confined  to  the  statutory  writ,  and,  like  that  writ,  be- 
came in  practice  absolete. 

(iii)  We  have  seen  that,  in  the  mediaeval  period,  it  had  been 
settled  that,  as  the  gist  of  the  action  on  the  case  was  not  the  con- 
spiracy but  the  damage,  it  could  be  brought  against  one  defendant- 
only.6  Does  it  not  follow,  therefore,  that  the  action  lay,  even  if 
the  malicious  indictment  had  been  preferred  by  one  defendant 
only  ?  In  other  words,  is  not  the  conspiracy  merely  a  circumstance 
of  aggravation,  and  not  a  necessary  part  of  the  cause  of  action  ? 
This  question  caused  much  division  of  judicial  opinion  in  Eliza- 
beth's reign.  In  1588,  in  the  case  of  Knight  v.  German,1  VVray, 
C.J.,  held  that  the  action  lay,  though  the  indictment  had  been  pre- 
ferred by  one  defendant  only ;  but  Schute  and  Gawdy,  J.  J.,  held 
that  it  would  not,  "for  then  every  felon  that  is  acquitted  will  sue 
an  action  against  the  party."  Later,  however,  Gawdy,  J.,  seems 
to  have  changed  his  opinion.8  Nevertheless  in  1597  Anderson, 
C.J.,  and  Beaumont,  J.,  expressed  the  opinion  that,  though  an 
action  lay  if  two  or  more  had  conspired  to  prefer  an  indictment, 
no  action  lay  where  one  only  had  preferred  it — which  opinion 
Walmsley,  J.,  doubted.9    But  though,  as  Parker,  C.J.,  said  in  Jones 

of  the  vexation  of  the  party,  and  so  it  is  all  one  whether  here  were  any  jurisdiction  or 
no,  for  the  plaintiff  is  prejudiced  by  the  vexation." 

1  Hunt  v.  Line  (1633),  cited  Jones  v.  Givin  (1713)  Gilbert  Cases  at  p.  212. 

2  Chamberlain  v.  Prescot,  as  reported  by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  Savile  v.  Roberts  (1098) 
1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  380. 

3  Below  391.  *  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  374. 
5(i7i3)  Gilbert  Cases  185. 

6  Vol.  iii  406-407  ;  Skinner  v.  Gunton  (1669)  1  Wins.  Saunders  at  pp.  229,  230. 

7  Cro.  Eliza.  70.  8  Ibid,  134. 

9 "  Where  two  or  more  conspire  together  to  procure  one  to  be  indicted  for 
felony  or  trespass,  and  he  is  afterwards  acquitted,  it  shall  be  intended  by  law  to  be 
maliciously  done,  for  which  conspiracy  lies  ;  but  no  action  lies  where  one  only  prefers 
a  bill  of  indictment ;  for  it  would  be  in  hinderance  of  justice.  .  .  .  WaJmsley 
doubted  thereof;  for  the  declaration  supposed  it  to  be  malitiose,"  Francis  Throg- 
morton's  Case  Cro.  Eliza,  at  p.  564. 


390  CRIME  AND  TORT 

v.  Giving  the  struggle  "was  strong  and  late  when  the  prosecution 
was  by  the  party  suffering  and  there  was  no  conspiracy,"  it  seems 
to  have  been  settled  in  the  course  of  the  seventeenth  century, 
perhaps  by  analogy  to  the  practice  of  the  Star  Chamber,  that  an 
action  would  lie  if  an  indictment  were  preferred  by  one  only.2 
Indeed,  it  was  hardly  possible  to  come  to  any  other  conclusion, 
as  it  was  clearly  settled  that  the  action  lay  for  malicious  accusations 
of  offences  under  the  degree  of  felony,  and  for  other  malicious 
abuses  of  the  process  of  the  courts,  though  committed  by  one 
person  only.  In  fact,  the  idea  that  the  conspiracy  to  indict  ma- 
liciously was  the  gist  of  the  offence  had  vanished  with  the  disuse 
of  the  statutory  writ  of  conspiracy ;  and  the  idea  that  the  conspiracy, 
as  such,  was  an  offence  had  become  associated  with  the  new 
crime  of  conspiracy,  which,  as  we  have  seen,3  rested  upon  a  very 
different  basis.  The  result  was  that  the  wrong  had  come  to  con- 
sist, not  in  the  conspiracy,  which,  if  present,  was  only  a  circum- 
stance of  aggravation,  but  in  the  act  of  malicious  prosecution,  or 
malicious  abuse  of  process.  This  fact  is  very  clearly  illustrated 
by  the  ruling  in  Manning  v.  Fitzherbert  in  1633,4  that,  as  the 
action  was  brought  for  the  unlawful  act  causing  damage  to  the 
plaintiff,  it  could  not  be  objected  to  an  action  for  such  unlawful 
act,  that  different  causes  of  action,  i.e.  for  the  unlawful  act  and 
for  the  conspiracy,  had  been  improperly  joined. 

These  developments  of  the  action  on  the  case  for  con- 
spiracy were  giving  rise  to  new  varieties  of  tort.  But,  though 
they  were  all  tending  in  this  direction,  the  cases  were  neither 
wholly  clear  nor  wholly  consistent.  Having  regard  to  the 
popularity  of  these  actions  for  malicious  prosecution,  and  the 
danger  to  the  proper  administration  of  the  criminal  law  of  al- 
lowing them  too  freely,5  this  new  branch  of  law  needed  a  clear 
and  authoritative  statement.  This  statement  was  furnished  in 
1699  by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  the  case  of  Savile  v.  Roberts?  That  case 
defined  the  conditions  under  which  the  action  on  the  case  could 

1  (1713)  Gilbert  Cases  at  p.  209. 

2  See  Manning  v.  Fitzherbert  (1633)  Cro.  Car.  271 ;  Carlion  v.  Mill  (1633)  Cro. 
Car.  291 ;  Norris  v.  Palmer  (1675)  2  Mod.  51  ;  cp.  Pollard  v.  Evans  (1679)  2  Shower, 
50,  where  the  statutory  writ  is  contrasted  with  the  action  on  the  case. 

3  Above  379-384. 

4  Cro.  Car.  271.  This  was  an  action  on  the  case  for  a  false  and  malicious  ac- 
cusation of  felony  before  a  justice  of  the  peace  ;  on  its  being  moved  in  arrest  of  judg- 
ment that  an  action  for  words,  and  an  action  in  the  nature  of  a  conspiracy,  had  been 
joined,  the  court  held  that,  "  it  is  not  in  nature  of  a  conspiracy,  but  an  aggravation  of 
the  false  and  malicious  accusation." 

6  In  1664  the  judges  refused  to  give  out  copies  of  indictments  for  felony  unless  on 
special  order,  "  for  the  late  frequency  of  actions  against  prosecutors  .  .  .  deterreth  people 
from  prosecuting  for  the  king  upon  just  occasions,"  Orders  of  the  Judges  in  1664, 
Kelyng  3  ;  and  this  practice  was  followed  by  Holt  and  in  Blackstone's  day,  see 
Thayer,  Evidence  230. 

8  (1693)  1  Ld.  Raym.  374 ;  S.C.  5  Mod.  405,  Carth.  416. 


MALICIOUS  PROSECUTION  391 

be  brought  for  a  malicious  prosecution,  and  thus  put  this  tort 
upon  its  modern  basis. 

It  was  in  substance  laid  down  that,  to  succeed  in  this  action, 
the  plaintiff  must  show,  firstly,  one  of  three  sorts  of  damage — 
damage  to  his  fair  fame,  damage  to  his  person  "  as  when  a  man  is 
put  in  danger  to  lose  his  life  limb  or  liberty,"  !  or  damage  to  his 
property  "  as  when  he  is  forced  to  expend  his  money  in  necessary 
charges  to  acquit  himself  of  the  crime  of  which  he  is  accused."2 
Secondly,  he  must  show  "  express  malice  and  iniquity  in  the 
prosecution."  3  Thirdly,  the  ground  of  the  action  is  not  the  con- 
spiracy but  the  damage,  and  therefore  the  action  will  lie,  though 
the  indictment  be  preferred  by  a  single  defendant  only.4  Fourthly, 
no  action  will,  as  a  rule,  lie  for  bringing  a  civil  action  maliciously. 
Under  the  old  law  the  amercement  of  the  plaintiff  who  thus  sued 
was,  and  under  the  modern  law  the  costs  awarded  to  a  successful 
defendant  are,  held  to  be  a  sufficient  compensation.5  But,  fifthly, 
the  bringing  of  an  action  maliciously,  or  a  malicious  use  of  the 
process  of  the  court,  may  give  rise  to  an  action  on  the  case,  if 
special  damage  be  proved.6  Lastly,  it  was  assumed,  as  it  is 
assumed  in  all  the  cases  both  on  the  statutory  writ  of  conspiracy 
and  on  the  action  on  the  case,  that  the  proceedings  must  have 
terminated  in  the  plaintiff's  favour.  All  these  propositions  were 
affirmed  in  the  elaborate  judgment  of  Parker,  C.J.,  in  171 3  in  the 
case  of  Jones  v.  Giving  in  which  an  elaborate  historical  account  is 
given  of  the  growth  of  this  branch  of  the  law. 

Thus  the  common  law  tort  of  conspiracy,  founded  upon  the 
statutory  writ  and  the  action  upon  the  case,  developed  into  the 
torts  of  malicious  prosecution,  and  other  malicious  abuses  of  the 
process  of  the  court  It  remains  to  enquire  whether  or  not  the 
law  has  recognized  a  new  tort  of  conspiracy,  corresponding  to  the 
new  crime  of  conspiracy  which  had  emerged  during  this  period. 


1 1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  378.  '  Ibid. 

s  Ibid  at  p.  381.  4  Ibid  at  p.  378. 

*  *'  The  common  law  has  made  provision  to  hinder  malicious  frivolous  and 
vexatious  suits,  that  every  plaintiff  should  find  pledges,  who  were  amerced  if  the  claim 
was  false.  .  .  .  But  that  method  became  disused,  and  then  to  supply  it,  the  statutes 
gave  costs  to  the  defendants.  And  though  this  practice  of  levying  of  amercements  be 
disused,  yet  the  Court  must  judge  according  to  the  reason  of  the  law,  and  not  vary 
their  judgments  by  accidents.  But  there  was  no  amercement  upon  indictments,  and 
the  party  had  not  any  remedy  to  reimburse  himself  but  by  action,"  ibid  at  p.  380. 

6  "  If  A  sues  an  action  against  B  for  mere  vexation,  in  some  cases  upon  particular 
damage  B  may  have  an  action  ;  but  it  is  not  enough  to  say  that  A  sued  him  falso  et 
malitiose,  but  he  must  show  the  matter  of  the  grievance  specially,  so  that  it  may 
appear  to  the  Court  to  be  manifestly  vexatious,"  ibid ;  changes  in  procedure  have 
rendered  this  cause  of  action  less  possible,  see  Quartz  Hill  Gold  Mining  Co.  v.  Eyre 
(1883)  11  Q.B.D.  at  pp.  6S9-691  per  Bowen,  L.J. ;  but  it  is  still  possible,  see  Clark  and 
Lindsell,  Torts  (4th  ed.)  659-660. 

7  Gilbert  Cases  185. 


392  CRIME  AND  TORT 

(3)  The  modern  tort  of  Conspiracy. 

The  question  whether  there  is  such  a  tort  as  conspiracy  is 
essentially  a  modern  question.  Very  little  authority  can  be  found 
on  it  before  the  latter  half  of  the  nineteenth  century;  and  the 
reason  for  this  dearth  of  authority  in  the  earlier,  and  its  extent  in 
the  later  period,  is  to  be  found  in  the  course  of  the  legislation  as 
to  the  application  of  the  doctrine  of  criminal  conspiracy  to  the 
activities  of  combinations  of  employers  and  workmen.  In  1875 
the  Legislature  enacted  that  a  combination  to  do  an  act  in  con- 
templation or  furtherance  of  a  trade  dispute,  should  not  be  indict- 
able as  a  conspiracy,  if  the  act  committed  by  one  person  would 
not  be  a  crime.1  But  it  was  held  that  this  enactment  did  not 
prevent  a  person  injured  by  such  a  conspiracy  from  bringing  a 
civil  action  for  the  damages  caused  by  it.2  Hence  the  tort  of 
conspiracy  was  brought  into  great  prominence.  But,  in  spite  of 
frequent  discussions  and  decisions  in  all  the  courts  from  the  House 
of  Lords  downwards,  neither  its  existence  as  a  specific  tort,  nor,  if  it 
exists,  its  precise  definition  was  settled  till  quite  recently.  Full  dis- 
cussion of  the  problem  would  here  be  out  of  place,  as  it  is  essentially 
a  problem  belonging  to  the  legal  history  of  the  nineteenth  century. 
But,  nevertheless,  the  legal  history  of  this  period  suggests  one  or  two 
considerations,  to  which  perhaps  sufficient  weight  has  not  been  at- 
tached in  the  many  discussions  to  which  the  problem  has  given  rise. 

Technically  this  is  a  problem  of  the  same  kind  as  that  to  which 
I  have  already  alluded  in  dealing  with  the  history  of  defamation.3 
A  crime  had  been  developed  by  the  court  of  Star  Chamber,  and, 
on  the  abolition  of  that  court,  the  crime  as  thus  developed  had 
become  a  common  law  misdemeanour.  If  that  misdemeanour  was 
committed,  and  a  person  was  damaged  thereby,  could  he  bring 
an  action  in  tort  ?  If  he  could,  what  was  the  nature  of  the  tort  ? 
What  was  the  connection,  if  any,  between  the  rules  applicable  to 
this  tort,  and  older  rules  of  the  common  law  as  to  the  same  or 
similar  wrongs  ?  Were  necessarily  all  the  rules  applicable  to  the 
crime  applicable  also  to  the  tort  ? 

We  have  seen  that,  in  the  case  of  defamation,  the  courts  had 
come  to  the  conclusion  that,  if  the  defamation  was  written,  so  that 
the  crime  of  libel  had  been  committed,  an  action  in  tort  lay  at  the 
suit  of  the  injured  party,  without  the  need  to  allege  and  prove 
special  damage.4  In  other  words,  the  development  of  the  crime 
of  libel  had  given  birth  to  the  tort  of  libel.  No  doubt  this  decision 
was  partly  due  to  the  extremely  unsatisfactory  character  of  the 
tort  which  had  been  developed  in  and  through  the  action  on  the 

1  38.  39  Victoria  c.  86  §  3. 

-  Quinn  v.  Leathern  [1901]  A.C.  at  p.  542  per  Lord  Lindley. 

y  Above  361-364.  *  Above  364-365. 


THE  MODERN  TORT  OF  CONSPIRACY     393 

case.  But  the  technical  justification  for  the  invention  of  the  new- 
tort  was  the  fact  that  written  defamation  was  a  crime.  It  would 
seem  that  exactly  the  same  principle  is  applicable  to  conspiracy  ; 
and  in  the  case  of  Pedro  v.  Barrett  in  16971  it  seems  to  be 
admitted.  The  report  of  that  case  runs  as  follows  : — "  A  brought 
case  against  B  for  falsely  and  maliciously  procuring  him  to  be 
indicted  for  conspiracy  to  lay  a  bastard  child  to  B,  of  which  indict- 
ment upon  trial  A  was  acquitted.  After  verdict  for  the  plaintiff 
upon  not  guilty  pleaded,  adjudged  that  the  action  well  lay,  for  the 
conspiracy  was  a  thing  punishable  at  common  law  by  fine  and  im- 
prisonment" No  doubt  these  words  were  spoken  of  the  common 
law  action  on  the  case  for  a  conspiracy,  which,  as  we  have  seen, 
developed  into  the  tort  of  malicious  prosecution  ;  but  the  general 
principle  there  laid  down  is  applicable  to  the  new  crime  of  con- 
spiracy, which  had  been  taken  over  by  the  common  law  courts 
from  the  Star  Chamber. 

But,  if  the  common  law  courts  were  to  recognize  a  tort  of  con- 
spiracy corresponding  to  the  crime,  had  this  tort  any  connection 
with  the  older  tort  of  conspiracy  remedied  by  the  action  on  the 
case  ?  It  would  seem,  at  first  sight,  that  the  connection  was 
slender.  The  element  of  conspiracy  had  vanished  from  the  older 
tort,  and  that  older  tort  had  become  the  tort  of  malicious  prosecu- 
tion. But  nevertheless  the  older  tort  left,  it  seems  to  me,  one 
permanent  legacy.  The  gist  of  the  action  on  the  case  was  the 
damage  suffered ;  and  it  was  because  this  was  the  gist  of  the 
action  that  the  element  of  conspiracy  had  been  eliminated.  In 
Savile  v.  Roberts2  it  was  argued  that  conspiracy,  being  "of  an 
odious  nature,"  was  "sufficient  ground  for  an  action  by  itself." 
But  to  this  argument  Holt,  C.  J.,  replied,  "  that  conspiracy  is  not 
the  ground  of  these  actions,  but  the  damages  done  to  the  party ; 
for  an  action  will  not  lie  for  the  greatest  conspiracy  imaginable, 
if  nothing  be  put  in  execution  ;  but  if  the  party  be  damaged  the 
action  will  lie."  Similarly,  there  has  never  been  any  doubt  that 
the  gist  of  the  tort  of  conspiracy  corresponding  to  the  new  crime 
of  conspiracy,  if  such  a  tort  exists,  is  the  damage  suffered  ;  and 
that  therefore  an  action  for  it  can  be  brought,  just  as  the  old  action 
could  be  brought,  against  one  defendant.3 

Now  this  has  a  very  material  bearing  on  the  question  whether 
or  not  all  the  rules  applicable  to  the  crime  are  also  applicable  to 
the  tort.  The  fact  that  the  conspiracy  is  the  essence  of  the  crime, 
while  the  damage  is  the  essence  of  the  tort,  must  make  a  great 
deal  of  difference  in  the  rules  applicable.     In  the  case  of  libel, 

1 1  Ld.  Raym.  81.  2  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  378. 

3  Quinn  v.  Leathern  [1901]  A.C.  at  p.  542 ;  cp.  Skinner  v.  Gunton  (1669)  1  W'ms. 
Saunders  at  pp.  229,  230. 


394  CRIME  AND  TORT 

where  the  difference  between  the  essential  features  of  the  crime 
and  the  tort  are  not  so  pronounced,  the  law  has  recognized  this 
difference.  Libel  is  regarded  as  a  crime,  because  libels,  if  un- 
punished, tend  to  promote  breaches  of  the  peace  ;  and  therefore 
a  publication  to  the  person  defamed  suffices,  and  the  truth  of  the 
defamatory  statement  was  not  a  defence,  and  is  not  now  a  defence, 
unless  it  is  for  the  public  benefit  that  the  truth  should  be  known. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  gist  of  libel  regarded  as  a  tort  is  the 
damage  inflicted  ;  and  therefore  the  publication  must  be  to  some 
third  person,  and  truth  is  a  defence.  Now  it  would  seem  that 
somewhat  similar  considerations  should  be  applied  to  determine 
the  question  of  the  relation  of  the  crime  of  conspiracy,  to  the  right 
of  the  party  injured  by  a  conspiracy  to  sue  in  tort.  In  both  cases 
we  must  look  at  the  nature  of  the  wrongs  redressed  by  the 
criminal  and  civil  remedy  respectively.  But  the  application  of 
these  considerations  will  not  produce  quite  the  same  results  as  in 
the  case  of  libel,  because,  as  I  have  said,  the  essential  features  of 
conspiracy  considered  as  a  crime  differ  more  markedly  from  con- 
spiracy considered  as  a  tort,  than  is  the  case  with  the  crime  and 
the  tort  of  libel.  The  crime  consists  in  the  conspiracy ;  but  the 
damage  is  the  gist  of  the  action  by  the  party  injured  by  the 
conspiracy — the  damage,  that  is,  flowing  from  the  unlawful  acts 
done  by  each  and  all  of  the  conspirators  in  pursuance  of  their 
joint  design.  What  we  must  look  at,  therefore,  in  order  to 
establish  a  cause  of  action,  is  not  so  much  the  conspiracy,  as  the 
quality  of  the  acts  and  the  damage  flowing  therefrom.  It  follows  that 
the  conspiracy  is  important,  not  as  establishing  directly  a  cause  of 
action  in  tort,  but,  firstly,  sometimes  as  showing  that  the  acts  done 
were  unlawful, because  they  amounted  to  a  criminal  conspiracy ;  and, 
secondly,  always  as  an  element  in  estimating  the  damage  suffered. 
This  seems  to  be  the  view  expressed  in  Mr.  Arthur  Cohen's 
memorandum  on  the  civil  action  of  conspiracy,  which  was  con- 
curred in  by  Lord  Dunedin  and  Sir  Godfrey  Lushington ; x  and 
we  shall  see  that  the  case  of  Sorrellv.  Smith*  which  contains  the 
latest  pronouncement  of  the  House  of  Lords  on  this  subject,  lays 
down  the  law  substantially  in  this  way. 

But  this  definition  of  the  scope  of  the  action  of  conspiracy 
has  not  been  reached  without  controversy.  It  may,  I  think,  be 
said  that  two  somewhat  divergent  views  as  to  its  scope  were  taken 
before  the  decision  in  the  case  of  Sorrell  v.  Smith? 

1  "  There  may  be  cases  where  the  combination  or  conspiracy  to  injure  is  itself  a 
misdemeanour,  although  the  acts  agreed  to  be  done  are  neither  actionable  torts  nor 
criminal  offences.  ...  In  such  cases  it  may  be  said  that  the  conspiracy  which  is  the 
misdemeanour  is  the  ground  of  the  civil  action.  These  however  are  the  only  cases  in 
which  it  can  in  propriety  be  said  that  a  civil  action  may  be  maintained  for  conspiracy," 
Report  of  Royal  Commission  on  Trade  Disputes  (1906)  at  p.  20. 

2  [x925]  A.C.  700.  3  Ibid. 


THE  MODERN  TORT  OF  CONSPIRACY     395 

(i)  According  to  one  set  of  authorities,  conspiracy  does  not 
exist  at  all  as  an  independent  tort.  The  tort  consists,  not  in 
the  conspiracy,  but  in  the  unlawful  acts  causing  damage  done  by 
each  and  all  of  the  conspirators.  This  view  would  seem 
to  have  the  support  of  Lord  Justice  Scrutton,1  of  Astbury- 
and  McCardie,  JJ.,3  and  of  Sir  F.  Pollock.4  If  this  con- 
clusion be  true,  it  would  follow  that  conspiracy  does  not  exist 
as  an  independent  tort.  The  tort  consists  in  the  unlawful  acts 
causing  damage  done  by  each  and  all  of  the  parties  to  a  conspiracy  ; 
and  the  conspiracy  is  only  important  as  a  circumstance  to  be 
taken  into  account  in  considering  the  legality  of  the  act  done,  and 
the  damage  inflicted.  If  this  be  the  law,  the  modern  development 
of  the  civil  remedy  for  acts  constituting  a  criminal  conspiracy 
presents  a  very  close  historical  parallel  to  the  development, 
during  the  seventeenth  century,  of  the  tort  remedied  by  the  older 
action  on  the  case  for  a  conspiracy.  Just  as  in  the  case  of  the 
older  remedy  the  element  of  conspiracy  ceased  to  be  the  gist  of 
the  action,  when  it  came  to  be  seen  that  its  gist  was  the  damage 
suffered  by  the  unlawful  act  of  the  defendant,  and  the  tort  came  to 
consist  in  the  commission  of  the  unlawful  act — in  the  malicious 
prosecution  or  the  malicious  abuse  of  the  process  of  the  courts  ; 
so,  in  the  case  of  the  modern  tort  of  conspiracy  developed  from 
the  new  crime  of  conspiracy,  the  element  of  conspiracy  ceases  to 
be  the  gist  of  the  action  for  exactly  the  same  reason ;  and  the 
tort  comes  to  consist,  not  in  the  conspiracy,  but  in  the  unlawful 
acts  which  have  caused  damage. 

(ii)  According  to  another  set  of  authorities  there  is  one  case 
in  which  the  existence  of  a  conspiracy  is  vital  to  existence  of  a 
cause  of  action.  The  clearest  statement  of  this  view  is  to  be 
found  in  Lord  Justice  Atkin's  judgment  in  the  case  of  Ware 
and  De  Freville  v.  Motor  Trade  Association.  The  Lord  Justice 
said : 5  "It  appears  to  me  to  be  beyond  dispute  that  the 
effect  of  the  two  decisions  in  Allen  v.  Flood  and  Quinn  v.  Leathern 
is  this :  that  on  the  one  hand  a  lawful  act  done  by  one  does  not 
become  unlawful  if  done  with  an  intent  to  injure  another,  whereas 
an  otherwise  lawful  act  done  by  two  or  more  in  combination  does 

1  "  Conspiracy  appears  to  me  to  become  actionable  when  the  end  is  unlawful  and 
causes  damage,  or  the  means  by  which  a  lawful  end  is  pursued  are  unlawful  and  cause 
damage,  and  not  to  be  actionable  when  neither  the  end  nor  the  means  are  unlawful. 
It  is  said  that  the  end  is  unlawful  if  it  is  to  cause  damage  to  another.  My  comment 
on  this  is  that  it  is  not  true,"  Ware  and  De  Freville  v.  Motor  Trade  Association  [1921] 
3  K.B.  at  p.  70. 

■  Valentine  v.  Hyde  [1919]  2  Ch.  at  pp.  149-150. 

3  Pratt  v.  British  Medical  Association  [1919]  1  K.B.  at  pp.  255-260. 

4  Torts  (12th  ed.)  321-329. 

5  [x921]  3  K.B.  at  pp.  90-91 ;  and  see  ibid  at  p.  84;  the  same  view  was  expressed 
by  Sargent,  J.,  in  the  case  of  Reynolds  v.  Shipping  Federation  Ltd.  [1924]  1  Ch.  at 
p.  40 ;  see  also  an  article  by  Mr.  Cheshire  in  L.Q.R.  xxxix  at  pp.  207-211. 


396  CRIME  AND  TORT 

become  unlawful  if  done  by  two  or  more  in  combination  with 
intent  to  injure  another.  That  it  is  the  combination  to  injure  that 
makes  the  act  unlawful  is  so  plainly  laid  down  in  Quinn  v.  Leathern 
that  it  seems  to  me  .  .  .  useless  ...  to  suggest  that  the  fact  of 
combination  in  that  case  was  only  an  incidental  feature  of  the 
case,  and  not  the  gist  of  the  matter."  It  would  seem  to  follow 
that,  according  to  this  view,  the  existence  of  a  conspiracy  may 
make  acts,  otherwise  lawful,  unlawful,  if  they  are  done  with  the 
intent  to  injure  another  person  ;  so  that,  on  this  view,  it  may  be 
contended  that  there  is  in  this  case  an  independent  tort  of 
conspiracy. 

This  year,  in  the  case  of  Sorrell  v.  Smith,1  Lord  Dunedin  has 
adjudicated  upon  the  whole  matter ;  and  it  seems  to  me  that  the 
result  of  his  judgment  is  a  very  skilful  reconciliation  of  these  two 
views.2  After  expressly  approving  Lord  Justice  Atkin's  state- 
ment of  the  law,3  he  points  out  that  it  must  not  be  forgotten 
that  a  combination  formed  with  intent  to  injure  another  is  a 
criminal  conspiracy,  and  so  an  unlawful  act.  If  a  civil  action  for 
conspiracy  is  based  on  the  existence  of  a  criminal  conspiracy,  a 
criminal  conspiracy  must  be  proved.  Such  a  conspiracy  exists 
if  several  persons  combine  to  do  acts  (lawful  or  unlawful)  with 
intent  to  injure  another.  It  does  not  exist  if  they  do  lawful  acts 
which  injure  another  person,  with  the  intent,  not  of  injuring  that 
other  person,  but  only  of  furthering  their  own  interests.4  It  is 
true  that  in  cases  in  which  the  element  of  conspiracy  is  not 
present,  intent  to  injure  another  will  not  make  an  otherwise 
lawful  act  unlawful.  But,  where  a  conspiracy  is  proved  to  exist, 
it  is  this  mens  rea — the  intent  to  injure — which,  in  the  case  ot 
the  crime  of  conspiracy,  as  in  the  case  of  other  crimes,  makes  all 
the  difference.  It  will  make  otherwise  lawful  acts  done  in  com- 
bination criminal,  and  so  unlawful.  It  comes  therefore  to  this — 
an  intent  to  injure  may  make  acts  illegal  as  a  criminal  conspiracy; 
and  so  these  acts  may  give  rise  to  an  action  in  tort  at  the  suit  of 
the  person  damaged  thereby,  although  the  same  acts  if  done  by 
one  person  would  give  rise  to  no  cause  of  action,  because  the 
existence  of  the  conspiracy  makes  acts,  otherwise  legal,  illegal. 
It  is  obvious  that  this  manner  of  reconciling  the  authorities  to 
some  extent  admits  the  truth  of  the  first  view,  by  allowing  that 
the  gist  of  the  action  is  the  unlawful  acts  causing  damage,  and  by 
making  the  element  of  conspiracy  essential  only  as  proof  that  the 
acts  done  were  unlawful — essential  only,  that  is,  in  those  cases  in 
which  the  existence  of  a  criminal  conspiracy  is  the  only  cause  of 

1  [1925]  A.C.  700.  -  Ibid  at  pp.  723-726.  3  Ibid  at  p.  719. 

4  Mogul  Steamship  Co.  v.  McGregor  Gow  and  Co.  [1892]  A.C.  25 ;  Sorrell  v. 
Smith  [1925]  A.C.  700. 


MAINTENANCE  397 

their  illegality.  It  follows  that,  as  was  said  in  1906,  it  is  only  in 
these  cases  that  "  it  may  be  said  that  the  conspiracy  is  the  ground 
of  the  civil  action."  x  It  is  only  in  these  cases  therefore  that  con- 
spiracy can  be  said  to  exist  as  an  independent  tort. 

This  controverted  question  as  to  the  existence  and  ambit  of 
the  tort  of  conspiracy  has  thus,  to  a  large  extent,  been  settled, 
after  half  a  century  of  keen  dispute.  On  that  settlement  two 
observations  may,  I  think,  be  made.  Firstly,  it  assumes  that  the 
crime  of  conspiracy  is  very  wide  in  its  ambit ; 2  for  it  assumes 
that  a  combination  to  do  any  act  is  a  criminal  conspiracy,  if  the 
intent  of  the  persons  combining  is  to  injure  another.  Secondly, 
it  makes  one  law  for  the  individual,  and  another  for  a  com- 
bination of  individuals ;  for  it  distinctly  decides  that  acts  done 
in  combination,  if  done  with  intent  to  injure,  are  actionable, 
although  the  same  acts  are  not  actionable  if  done  by  one  person. 
That  this  may  lead  to  very  anomalous  results  is  clear ;  for,  as 
Lord  Lindley  said  in  Quinn  v.  Leathern,  if  one  man  acting  alone 
could  produce  the  same  effects  as  several  acting  together,  he 
ought  to  be  liable  in  the  same  way.3  This  anomaly  would,  it  is 
true,  have  been  avoided,  if  Allen  v.  Flood*  had  been  decided 
differently,  and  the  views  of  Lord  Esher  in  Temperton  v.  Russell '5 
had  been  upheld.  But  it  may  well  be  that  in  that  case  the  law 
would  have  laid  itself  open  to  the  criticism  that  it  restricted  un- 
duly individual  liberty  of  action ;  and  it  is  difficult  to  see  how 
any  such  views  could  be  reconciled  with  the  ratio  decidendi  of 
Mayor  of  Bradford  v.  Pickles*  and  Allen  v.  Flood?  Probably,  in 
the  existing  state  of  the  authorities,  the  solution  reached,  though 
it  may  conceivably  lead  to  some  anomalous  results,  is  the  best 
compromise.  At  any  rate  it  has  the  merit  of  recognizing  that 
there  is  generally  a  danger  in  concerted  action,  which  is  not 
generally  present  in  individual  action — of  recognising,  in  other 
words,  the  root  principle  upon  which  the  whole  law  of  conspiracy 
rests. 

Maintenance 

I  have  already  spoken  of  the  mediaeval  development  of  the 
offence  of  maintenance.  We  have  seen  that,  as  the  result  of  that 
development,  it  had  become  a  recognized  offence  redressible  both 
by  a  criminal  and  a  civil  remedy ;  and  that,  when  Coke  wrote,  it 

1  Above  394  n.  i.  a  Above  381. 

3 "  One  man  exercising  the  same  control  over  others  as  these  defendants  had 
could  have  acted  as  they  did,  and,  if  he  had  done  so,  I  conceive  that  he  would  have 
committed  a  wrong  towards  the  plaintiff,  for  which  the  plaintiff  could  have  maintained 
an  action,"  [1901]  A.C.  at  p.  537;  cp.  Sorrell  v.  Smith  [1925]  A.C.  at  p.  713  per  Lord 
Cave,  and  at  pp.  740-741  per  Lord  Sumner. 

4  [1898]  A.C.  i.  *  [1893]  1  Q.B.  at  pp.  728-730. 

«  [1895]  A.C.  587 ;   below  448.  »  [1898]  A.C.  1. 


398  CRIME  AND  TORT 

had  assumed  substantially  its  modern  form.1  That  it  had  then 
assumed  its  modern  form  was  due  principally  to  three  causes.  In 
the  first  place,  we  have  seen  that  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Council 
and  the  Star  Chamber  had  sternly  repressed  those  abuses  of  legal 
procedure,  which  had  made  maintenance  one  of  the  most  crying 
evils  of  the  later  mediaeval  period.2  In  the  second  place,  changes 
in  the  law  of  procedure,  and  more  especially  the  beginnings  of 
the  modern  law  of  evidence,3  had  rendered  obsolete  some  of 
the  mediaeval  cases,  which  had  laid  it  down  that  the  mere  giving 
of  unsolicited  testimony  would  amount  to  maintenance.4  In  the 
third  place,  we  have  seen  that  it  was  beginning  to  be  recognized 
that  it  was  not  every  assignment  of  a  chose  in  action  which  could 
be  attacked  on  the  ground  of  maintenance.5  It  is  true  that 
reminiscences  of  the  period  when  maintenance  was  so  crying  an 
evil,  that  to  relax  in  any  way  these  rules  as  to  non-assignability, 
would  have  operated  to  increase  it,  lived  on  in  this  branch  of  the 
law  long  after  it  had  become  a  comparatively  rare  offence  ; 6  and 
it  is  true  also  that  the  fact  that  many  of  the  older  rules  were 
obviously  ill  suited  to  a  more  settled  age  sometimes  induced 
judges  to  speak  as  if  they  thought  that  it  was  a  semi-obsolete 
offence.7  But  though,  for  these  three  reasons,  the  offence  had 
both  altered  its  character  and  become  far  less  frequent,  it  is  an 
offence  which  in  any  political  society  is  as  ineradicable  as  larceny 
or  homicide.  Therefore  a  thin  stream  of  cases,  from  the  seven- 
teenth to  the  twentieth  century,  has  recognized  it,  and  defined 
its  modern  incidents. 

It  is  a  commonplace  of  legal  history  that  the  form  of  the 
remedies  given  to  redress  a  particular  wrong,  or  assert  a  par- 
ticular right,  has  had  a  decisive  influence  in  settling  the  form 
and  content  of  that  wrong  or  that  right.  But  it  is  no  less  true 
that  changes  in  political  and  social  conditions  have  often  affected 
the  litigant's  choice  of  the  remedies  open  to  him ;  and  thus  the 
disuse  of  some  of  the  remedies  provided  by  the  law,  and  the  more 
extended  use  of  others,  have  operated  to  make  a  change  in  the 
character  of  the  wrong  redressed,  or  the  right  protected,  by  these 
remedies.  We  get  a  particularly  good  illustration  of  this  process 
of  development  in  the  case  of  maintenance.  We  have  seen  that, 
all  through  the  Middle  Ages,  and  right  down  to  Henry  VII I. 's 
reign,  it  was  treated  as  a  criminal  offence,  for  which  the  offender 
could  be  punished,  or  for  which  (under  Henry  VIII.'s  statute)  an 
action  for  a  penalty  could  be  brought.8     But  we  have  seen  that, 

1  Vol.  iii  395-399.  a  Vol.  v  201-203.  3  Vol.  ix  c.  7  §  1. 

4  Vol.  i  334-335  5  vol.  iii  398.  5  Vol.  vii  536.  6  Ibid  533,  535. 

7  See  the  remarks  of  Buller,  J.,  in  Master  v.  Miller  (1791)  4  T.R.  at  pp.  340-341. 

8  32  Henry  VIII.,  c.  9  §  3  ;  vol.  iii  396-397  ;  vol.  iv  521 ;  vol.  v  202. 


MAINTENANCE  399 

during  the  Middle  Ages,  it  was  recognized  that  it  could  also  be 
redressed  by  an  action  at  the  suit  of  the  party.1  The  law  is  so 
stated  by  Coke  in  the  seventeenth  century,2  and  by  Hawkins  in 
the  eighteenth  century ; 3  and,  when  maintenance  ceased  to  be  so 
crying  an  evil,  the  criminal  remedy  (though  still  available)  tended 
to  drop  out,  and  to  be  replaced  by  the  action  for  damages.  Thus 
in  modern  law  maintenance  came  to  be  regarded  as  a  tort  rather 
than  as  a  crime.  Naturally  the  question  arises,  what  is  the 
nature  of  this  tort  ? 

No  doubt  its  main  essential  features  are  the  same  as  those  of 
the  crime.  We  have  seen  that  the  definition  of  the  offence,  both 
at  common  law  and  according  to  the  law  administered  in  the 
Star  Chamber,  and  the  cases  in  which,  on  account  of  relationship 
or  otherwise,  maintenance  was  justifiable,  were  substantially  settled 
at  the  beginning  of  the  seventeenth  century.4  But  the  question 
still  remains  whether  all  the  essential  features  of  the  tort  re- 
dressible  by  the  civil  action,  are  the  same  as  the  criminal  offence 
created  by  that  long  line  of  mediaeval  statutes  which  end  with  the 
statute  of  1 540.5  This,  it  will  be  observed,  is  a  problem  of  a  very 
similar  kind  to  that  with  which  we  have  been  faced  in  dealing 
with  the  history  of  defamation6  and  conspiracy."  All  the  con- 
ditions of  the  problem  are  not,  it  is  true,  exactly  the  same.  In 
the  first  two  cases  we  have  two  lines  of  development — a  line  of 
development,  mainly  civil,  in  the  common  law  courts,  and  a  line 
of  development,  mainly  criminal,  in  the  Star  Chamber;  and  we 
were  obliged  to  consider  the  relation  between  the  criminal  offence 
developed  in  the  latter  court,  and  the  civil  offence  which  was  later 
developed  from  it.  In  the  case  of  maintenance  we  have  an 
offence  created  by  statutes,  which  were  enforced  both  by  the 
common  law  courts  and  the  court  of  Star  Chamber ;  and  this 
offence  could  be  treated  as  either  a  criminal  offence  punishable  on 
an  indictment,  or  as  a  civil  wrong  redressible  by  an  action  for 
damages.  Gradually  the  criminal  remedy  dropped  out,  and  the 
offence  came  to  be  treated  as  a  tort  redressible  by  an  action  for 
damages.  In  the  first  two  cases  the  civil  action  was  clearly  an 
action  on  the  case,  in  which  damage  was  the  gist  of  the  action  ; 
but  in  the  case  of  maintenance  it  was  not  certain  that  the  civil 
action  was  not  an  action  in  the  nature  of  an  action  for  trespass,  in 
which  nominal  damages  could  be  recovered.     But,    in   spite  of 

1  Vol.  iii  397-398-  2  Second  Instit.  208. 

3  "  All  offenders  of  this  kind  are  not  only  liable  to  an  action  of  maintenance  at 
the  suit  of  the  party  grieved,  wherein  they  shall  render  such  damages  as  shall  be 
answerable  to  the  injury  done  to  the  plaintiff,  but  also  they  may  be  indicted  as 
offenders  against  public  justice,"  P.C.  Bk.  i  c.  83  §  35. 

*  Vol.  iii  398  ;  vol.  v  202-203.  532  Henry  VIII.  c.  9. 

15  Above  361-364.  "  Above  392-394. 


400  CRIME  AND  TORT 

these  differences,  in  all  these  cases  the  problem  raised  was  the 
same — whether  or  not  all  the  features  of  the  tort  were  the  same 
as  all  the  features  of  the  criminal  offence. 

Curiously  enough  this  problem  was  not  fully  considered  by  the 
courts  till  1 91 9,  when  it  was  raised  by  the  case  of  Neville  v.  the 
London  Express  Newspaper  Ltd}  That  case  raised  the  two  closely 
connected  questions  (i)  whether  an  action  for  maintenance  would 
lie  in  the  absence  of  proof  of  special  damage  ;  and  (ii)  whether  the 
success  of  the  maintained  litigation  was  a  bar  to  the  action. 

(i)  On  principle  it  would  seem  that,  if  the  civil  action  for  main- 
tenance is  to  be  regarded  as  an  action  in  the  nature  of  an  action 
on  the  case,  damage  is  its  gist ;  and  that,  on  that  hypothesis,  the 
decision  of  the  majority  of  the  House  of  Lords,2  that  the  action  did 
not  lie  in  the  absence  of  the  proof  of  special  damage  was  right. 
The  opinion  of  the  two  dissentient  lords  seems  to  have  proceeded 
on  the  ground  that,  maintenance  being  admittedly  illegal,  the  law 
should  give  a  right  of  action  in  tort  for  nominal  damages  as  in  the 
case  of  trespass  or  libel,  "  since  the  mere  invasion  of  the  plaintiff's 
legal  right  imports  damage,  and  is  sufficient  to  maintain  the  action." 3 
But  the  fact  that  conduct  is  illegal,  or  even  criminal,  does  not 
necessarily  prove  that  an  action  in  tort  for  nominal  damages  will 
lie.  This  is  clearly  the  law  in  the  case  of  conspiracy,  as  the  passage 
from  the  case  of  Savile  v.  Roberts}  cited  above,  and  the  modern 
cases 5  show.  No  doubt  an  opposite  conclusion  was  come  to  in 
the  case  of  libel.  But  that,  as  we  have  seen,6  was  largely  due  to 
the  need  for  remedying  the  defects  of  the  common  law  action  on 
the  case,  which  had  wholly  failed  to  provide  a  satisfactory  civil 
remedy  for  defamation.  The  action  is,  as  we  have  seen,  somewhat 
anomalous ;  and  the  fact  that  an  action  on  the  case  for  defamation 
lies  for  nominal  damages  is  the  result  of  the  peculiar  history  of  this 
tort.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  civil  action  is  to  be  regarded,  not 
as  an  action  on  the  case,  but  as  a  statutory  or  common  law  action 
analogous  to  trespass,  there  is  a  good  deal  more  to  be  said  for  the 
view  that  an  action  would  lie  for  nominal  damages.  The  obscurity 
which  hangs  about  the  nature  of  the  civil  action  naturally  gives  rise 
to  differences  of  opinion.  But,  on  the  whole,  whatever  the  earlier 
law  may  have  been,  the  action  of  maintenance  had  probably  come, 
in  the  eighteenth  century,  to  be  regarded  as  similar  to  other  actions 
on  the  case ;  and,  if  that  be  so,  the  general  rule  is  that  laid  down 
by  Holt,  C.J.,  in  Savile  v.  Roberts.     It  follows  that  the  general 

Jfigig]  A.C.  368. 

2  Lords  Finlay,  Shaw,  and  Phillimore;  Lords  Haldane  and  Atkinson  dissenting, 

3  Per  Lord  Atkinson  at  p.  405. 

4  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  378,  cited  above  393. 

5  Above  395-397.  6  Above  364. 


MAINTENANCE  401 

rule  was  quite  properly  applied  by  the  majority  of  the  House  of 
Lords  to  the  case  of  maintenance. 

(ii)  On  the  other  hand,  the  reasons  given  by  the  majority  of 
the  House  of  Lords  for  holding  that  the  success  of  the  maintained 
action  is  not  a  bar  to  a  right  of  action  for  maintenance,  are  by  no 
means  convincing.  They  proceed  mainly  on  the  ground  that,  as 
all  maintenance  is  a  wrong,  the  success  or  failure  of  the  action 
maintained  can  have  nothing  to  do  with  the  question  whether  or 
no  a  wrong  was  committed.1  But,  to  argue  from  the  proposition 
that  maintenance  is  a  wrong,  to  the  conclusion  that  a  plaintiff  can 
sue  for  damages,  in  a  case  where  the  action  or  defence  maintained 
was  just,  comes  very  near  to  contradicting  the  rule,  upheld  by  the 
majority  of  the  House,  that  such  an  action  will  not  lie  for  nominal 
damages.  It  may  well  be  that  maintenance  is  a  wrong,  and  that 
the  criminal  offence  is  committed,  whether  or  no  the  maintained 
litigation  has  succeeded  or  failed.2  It  may  well  be  that  the  same 
conclusion  follows,  if  maintenance  is  a  tort  like  trespass,  for  which 
an  action  will  lie  for  nominal  damages.  But,  if  it  is  only  a  tort  when 
accompanied  by  special  damage,  if  the  damage,  that  is,  is  the  gist  of 
the  action,  it  does  not  follow  that,  because  the  crime  is  committed, 
the  tort  is  likewise  committed,  when  the  maintained  litigation  has 
succeeded.  We  have  seen  that,  in  the  case  of  the  torts  both  of 
libel  and  conspiracy,  it  does  not  follow  that,  because  the  crime  has 
been  committed,  the  tort  has  also  been  committed.  In  both  cases 
the  conditions  under  which  an  action  of  tort  will  lie  differ  from 
the  conditions  under  which  an  indictment  can  be  preferred.  Lord 
Phillimore,  one  of  the  Lords  who  dissented  from  the  majority  of 
the  House  on  this  point,  very  properly  used  the  analog}'  of  libel 
to  illustrate  his  argument ; 3  and  he  might  equally  well  have  used 
the  analogy  of  conspiracy.  The  result  is  that  the  House  has  com- 
mitted itself  to  two  rules  which,  if  not  actually  contradictory,  are 
extremely  hard  to  reconcile.  For,  though  the  success  of  the  main- 
tained litigation  is  not  a  bar  to  the  action,  it  is  clear  that  its 
success  will  generally  prevent  the  plaintiff  from  claiming  anything 
but  nominal  damages ; 4  and  for  nominal  damages,  the  action, 
according  to  the  first  proposition,  does  not  lie. 

In  fact  the  House  of  Lords,  though  it  appealed  to  history,  and 
even  to  the  Year  Books,  hardly  perceived  that  the  problem  was 
essentially  similar  to  the  problem  which  the  development  of  the 

1  See  [1919]  A.C.  at  pp.  383-386,  392-393,  397-404. 

2  Coke,  dealing  with  the  case  of  one  who  had  laboured  a  jury,  says,  "  and  whether 
the  jury  pass  for  his  side  or  no,  or  whether  the  jury  give  any  verdict  at  all,  yet  he  shall 
be  punished  as  a  maintainor  or  embraceor  either  at  the  suit  of  the  king  or  party,"  Co. 
Litt.  36ga ;  from  the  use  of  the  word  "  punished  "  it  would  seem  that  Coke  is  referring 
to  the  criminal  remedy. 

3  [1919]  A.C.  at  p.  434.  *  See  ibid  at  pp.  380-381,  393,  395. 
VOL.   VIII.— 26 


402  CRIME  AND  TORT 

law  of  crime  and  tort  in  the  seventeenth  century  had  raised  in  the 
case  both  of  defamation  and  conspiracy.  Given  an  offence  which 
was  a  crime,  on  what  conditions  could  a  person  injured  by  the 
crime  sue  in  tort  for  any  damage  which  he  had  suffered?  If  it 
had  looked  at  the  question  in  its  proper  historical  perspective,  it 
could  hardly  have  avoided  coming  to  a  less  contradictory  con- 
clusion than  that  at  which  it  has  actually  arrived ;  for  it  would 
have  avoided  the  error  into  which,  as  it  seems  to  me,  many  of  the 
Lords  fell,  of  supposing  that,  because  an  act  is  a  crime,  the  same 
act  must,  without  qualification,  necessarily  be  a  tort.  If  it  had 
grasped  this  principle  it  would  probably  have  ruled  that,  just  as 
the  conditions  under  which  the  tort  and  crime  of  libel  or  conspiracy 
can  be  committed  differ,  so  do  the  conditions  applicable  to  the  tort 
and  crime  of  maintenance ;  that  just  as  publication  to  a  third 
party  is  needed  to  constitute  the  tort,  though  not  the  crime  of 
libel,  and  just  as  an  act  causing  damage  to  the  plaintiff  is  needed 
to  constitute  the  tort,  though  not  the  crime  of  conspiracy ;  so  the 
failure  of  the  maintained  litigation  is  needed  to  constitute  the  tort, 
though  not  the  crime,  of  maintenance. 

§  4.  Legal  Doctrines  Resulting  from  the  Laws  against 
Religious  Non-Conformity 

In  the  preceding  volumes  of  this  work  I  have  given  some 
account  of  the  statutes  which  penalized  various  forms  of  non- 
conformity to  the  established  church.1  In  this  section  I  propose 
to  give  some  account  of  the  developments  of  legal  doctrine  to 
which  these  statutes  helped  to  give  rise,  and  of  the  corresponding 
changes  in  that  doctrine  which  followed  upon  their  repeal. 

The  result  of  these  statutes  was  to  create  a  number  of  offences, 
which  may  be  called  offences  against  either  the  religion  of  the 
state,  or  the  Christian  religion  in  general.  If  we  look  at  the 
dates  at  which  they  were  enacted,  it  will  be  clear  that  the  history 
of  these  offences,  regarded  as  offences  against  the  law  of  the  state, 
as  distinct  from  offences  against  the  ecclesiastical  law,  does  not 
begin  till  the  Reformation  period.  During  the  Middle  Ages 
such  offences  were  essentially  matters  for  the  ecclesiastical  law, 
and  the  function  of  the  state  was  limited  to  lending  the  strength 
of  its  secular  arm  to  enforce  the  decrees  of  the  church.  We  have 
seen  that  the  state  recognized  and  obeyed  the  law  of  the  church, 
which,  till  the  Reformation,  was  the  papal  canon  law ; 2  and  that 
it  was  because  it  so  recognized  it  that  the  writ  de  haeretico  com- 
burendo  must  be  regarded  as  existing  at  common  law.3     The  fact 

1  Vol.  i  616-619 ;  vol.  iv  494-496,  506-507  ;  vol.  vi  196-203,  404. 

2  Vol.  i  580-588  ;  vol.  ii  304-306.  3  Vol.  i  616-618. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        408 

that  the  Reformation  of  the  English  church  was  carried  through 
with  the  minimum  of  change,  so  that  the  thesis  of  its  continuity 
could  be  maintained  both  by  lawyers  and  ecclesiastics ; l  and  the 
fact  that  English  law,  during  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries,  was  likewise  continuously  developed  from  its  mediaeval 
principles — ensured  that,  at  the  outset,  the  attitude  of  the  law 
towards  these  offences  against  religion  should  be  essentially 
mediaeval.  During  the  Tudor  period,  as  in  the  mediaeval  period, 
Church  and  State  were  regarded,  from  many  points  of  view,  as  a 
single  society  which  had  many  common  objects ;  -  and  the  two 
members  of  that  single  society  were  still  regarded  as  bound  to 
give  one  another  assistance  in  carrying  out  those  common  objects. 
The  church  must  help  the  state  to  maintain  its  authority,  and  the 
state  must  help  the  church  to  punish  non-conformists  and  infidels. 
The  church  was  the  church  of  the  state,  and  membership  of  it 
was  therefore  a  condition  precedent  for  full  rights  in  the  state ; 
the  king  was  the  supreme  governor  of  the  church ; 3  and  the  law 
of  the  church  was  the  king's  ecclesiastical  law.4  But,  if  the 
church  is  thus  regarded  as  an  integral  part  of  the  state,  if  the 
church's  law  is  as  much  the  king's  law  as  the  law  of  the  state, 
a  fortiori  Christianity  must  be  regarded  as  part  of  the  law  of 
England.  In  fact,  not  only  Christianity,  but  also  that  particular 
variety  of  Christianity  taught  by  the  Anglican  church,  was  part  of 
that  law.5 

In  our  day  this  theory  of  the  relationship  between  Church  and 
State  has  almost  entirely  disappeared.  It  is  true  that  there  is 
still  an  established  church ;  that  the  king  is  still  its  supreme 
governor  and  the  defender  of  its  faith ;  that  its  law  is  still  the 
king's  ecclesiastical  law,  and  an  integral  part  of  the  law  of 
England.6  But,  like  many  other  parts  of  the  law  and  con- 
stitution of  England,  these  are  survivals  of  an  older  order,  from 
which  all  real  meaning  has  departed,  with  the  abandonment  of 

1  Vol.  i  591.  2  Vol.  iv  36-37,  47-48,  81-83. 

3  Vol.  i  594.  *  Ibid  594-590- 

'Professor  Kenny  in  Cambridge  Law  Journal  i  130-131  has  contended  that  the 
maxim  or  rule  that  "  Christianity  is  part  of  the  law  of  England "  is  derived  from 
Finch's  book  on  the  Common  Law  (vol.  v  399-401) ;  and  that  Finch  derived  it  from 
a  statement  made  by  Prisot,  C.J.,  in  Y.B.  34  Hy.  VI.  Pasch.  pi.  9,  p.  38,  which  is 
probably  no  authority  for  this  wide  proposition.  But  for  the  reasons  which  I  have 
given  in  the  text  I  think  that  the  rule  or  maxim  would,  from  the  earliest  times,  have 
been  accepted  as  almost  self-evident  by  English  lawyers.  It  is  assumed  both  by 
Fortescue,  vol.  ii  56g,  n.  3,  and  by  St  Germain,  vol.  iv  279-280 ;  and  it  is  at  the  root 
of  the  old  distinction  between  mala  prohibita  and  mala  in  se,  vol.  vi  218-219.  But, 
for  that  very  reason,  it  was  difficult  to  find  an  express  authority  for  it,  see  the  dictum 
of  James,  L.J.,  cited  vol.  ii  470 ;  and  it  was  probably  because  Finch  was  hard  put  to 
it  to  find  any  authority  precisely  in  point,  that  he  cited  this  Y.B.  For  these  reasons  I 
cannot  agree  with  Professor  Kenny  that  Finch's  misquotation  disproves  the  existence 
of  the  doctrine. 

6  Vol.  i  595. 


404  CRIME  AND  TORT 

that  mediaeval  theory  of  the  relationship  of  Church  to  State, 
to  which  they  owed  their  origin.1  That  that  theory  has  been 
completely  abandoned  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  the  state  now 
assumes  the  attitude  of  a  Gallio  to  religion.  It  gives  an  equal 
measure  of  protection  to  all  sects,  whether  religious  or  anti- 
religious,  provided  that  their  tenets  do  not  involve  a  breach  of 
its  laws  civil  or  criminal.  It  refuses  to  favour  one  more  than 
another ;  and  practically  the  only  coercive  authority  which  it 
exercises,  is  in  respect  of  those  whose  methods  of  propaganda 
are  sufficiently  coarse  and  offensive  to  bring  them  within  the 
modern  rules  of  the  criminal  law  relating  to  blasphemous  libel. 

This  vast  change  in  the  relations  of  Church  and  State  has 
been  mainly  the  result  of  that  policy  of  "conservatism  combined 
with  concession,"  which  has  been  pursued  during  the  nineteenth 
century.2  But  that  policy  has  its  roots  in  the  past;  and  the 
modern  relations  of  Church  and  State  are  in  fact  the  result  of 
some  four  centuries  of  its  application.  Its  application  has  neces- 
sarily involved  many  statutory  changes  in  the  law,  and  many 
gradual  modifications  in  the  technical  doctrines  of  the  law  to 
correspond  with  the  statutory  changes ;  and,  as  the  result  of  the 
modifications  of  these  technical  doctrines,  changes  in  the  attitude 
of  the  courts  to  the  interpretation  of  the  statutes.  Therefore,  in 
relating  the  history  of  these  changes  both  of  the  statute  law  and 
of  the  technical  doctrines  of  English  law,  we  must  take  account 
of  many  diverse  lines  of  development,  which  have  operated  at 
different  periods.  If  we  look  at  these  lines  of  development  from 
the  point  of  view  of  their  chronological  order,  we  can,  I  think,  sum 
them  up  briefly  as  follows : 

Till  the  outbreak  of  the  Great  Rebellion,  the  part  played  by 
the  ecclesiastical  law  in  the  repression  of  all  offences  against 
religion,  was  by  no  means  inconsiderable.3  It  did  not  indeed 
play  so  large  a  part  as  in  the  Middle  Ages ;  for  it  was  controlled 
by  statutes,  which  were  enforced  by  the  common  law  courts, 
and  it  was  both  controlled  and  supplemented  by  the  rules  and 
doctrines  of  the  common  law.4  We  have  seen  that,  in  the  latter 
half  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  influence  of  the  ecclesiastical 

1  Below  416-417. 

8  Dicey,  Law  and  Public  Opinion  (1st  ed.)  316 — "  In  all  ecclesiastical  matters 
Englishmen  have  favoured  a  policy  of  conservatism  combined  with  concession.  Con- 
servatism has  here  meant  deference  for  the  convictions,  sentiments,  or  prejudices  of 
churchmen,  whenever  respect  for  ecclesiastical  feeling  did  not  cause  palpable  incon- 
venience to  laymen,  or  was  not  inconsistent  with  obedience  to  the  clearly  expressed 
will  of  the  nation.  Concession  has  meant  readiness  to  sacrifice  the  privileges,  or  defy 
the  principles,  dear  to  churchmen,  whenever  the  maintenance  thereof  was  inconsistent 
with  the  abolition  of  patent  abuses,  the  removal  of  grievances,  or  the  carrying  out  of 
reforms  demanded  by  classes  sufficiently  powerful  to  represent  the  voice,  or  to  com- 
mand the  acquiescence  of  the  country." 

3  Vol.  i  617-620.  4  Ibid  617-618,  620-621 ;  below  406-407. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        405 

law  rapidly  declined.1  This  was  partly  due  to  the  dislike  of 
allowing  to  the  ecclesiastical  courts  any  coercive  authority  over 
laymen — a  dislike  which  found  expression  in  statutory  changes 
which  crippled  this  part  of  the  jurisdiction  of  these  courts,  and 
practically  limited  it  to  a  jurisdiction  over  the  clergy.2  Partly 
also  it  was  due  to  the  increased  control  of  the  common  law 
courts.  But,  for  a  considerable  time,  the  law  administered  by 
these  common  law  courts  maintained  much  of  the  spirit  of  the 
old  system.  The  statute  law  had  made  even  Christian  non- 
conformity illegal,  and  had  penalized  the  various  sects,  whether 
Protestant  or  Roman  Catholic,  in  different  ways  and  degrees.3 
A  fortiori  any  anti-Christian  propaganda  must  be  regarded  as 
illegal.4  Though  a  small  breach  had  been  made  in  this  system 
by  the  Toleration  Act  of  1689,5  and  by  the  liberal  way  in  which 
it  was  interpreted,6  it  continued  to  be  the  foundation  upon  which 
the  law  rested  till  the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century.  But, 
during  the  earlier  half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  a  still  larger 
breach  was  made  by  the  repeal  of  nearly  all  the  older  statutes 
which  penalized  Christian,  and  even  non-Christian,  nonconformity.7 
Very  few  restrictions  were  left  upon  the  holding  and  exercise  of 
any  kind  of  religious  belief.  But,  except  as  modified  by  these 
statutes,  the  common  law  rules,  criminal  and  civil,  as  to  the 
illegality  of  the  expression  and  teaching  of  definitely  anti-Christian 
beliefs,  were  left  untouched.  There  had  been  no  formal  change 
in  these  rules,  which  were  founded  on  the  principle  that,  as 
Christianity  was  part  of  the  law,  any  attack  on  it  was  unlawful.8 
It  was  however  inevitable  that,  in  the  atmosphere  of  universal 
toleration,  which  was  partly  the  cause  and  partly  the  effect  of 
these  statutes,  these  common  law  rules  and  doctrines  should 
change  their  form  and  scope.  It  came  to  be  thought  that  the 
expression  and  teaching  of  anti-Christian  beliefs  was  only  criminal 
if  it  amounted  to  blasphemous  libel,  and  that  the  reverend  ques- 
tioning of  those  beliefs  entailed  no  criminal  liability.9  In  the 
twentieth  century  the  propagation  of  these  beliefs  was  held  to  be 
lawful  for  all  purposes,  so  that  it  has  become  possible  to  establish 
a  trust  for  their  maintenance.10  Lastly,  these  changes  in  common 
law  doctrine  have  reacted  on  the  manner  in  which  some  of  the 
earlier  statutes,  which  gave  only  a  modified  relief  to  Roman 
Catholics,  have  been  interpreted ;  with  the  result  that  the 
modifications  and  restrictions  contained  in  these  statutes  have 
been,  to  all  intents  and  purposes,  rendered  nugatory.11 

1  Vol.  i  620-621.  2  Ibid  621. 

3  Vol.  iv  494-496,  506-507;  vol.  vi  196-203.  *  Below  407-410. 

5  1  William  and  Mary  c.  18  ;  vol.  vi  200-201 ;  below  410-411. 

8  Below  411.  7  Below  41 1-413.  8  Below  413-414. 

9  Below  415-416.  10  Below  416.  n  Below  417-41S. 


406  CRIME  AND  TORT 

It  will  be  clear  from  this  summary  of  the  development  of  this 
branch  of  the  law,  that  its  history  falls  into  certain  well-marked 
periods.  They  can  be  classified  as  follows: — (i)  The  relation 
between  law  and  religion  in  the  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  cen- 
turies ;  (2)  the  new  situation  created  by  the  repeal  or  modification 
of  the  legislation  against  religious  nonconformity ;  (3)  the  effect 
of  this  new  situation  upon  legal  doctrines  as  to  the  relation  be- 
tween law  and  religion ;  (4)  the  effect  of  this  new  common  law 
doctrine  upon  the  interpretation  of  the  older  legislation.  Under 
these  four  heads  I  propose  to  sketch  the  history  of  the  develop- 
ment of  this  branch  of  the  law. 

(1)  The  relation  between  law  and  religion  in  the  seventeenth  and 
eighteenth  centuries. 

During  the  whole  of  this  period  the  relations  between  law  and 
religion  retained  something  of  their  mediaeval  character,  in  that 
the  law  considered  it  to  be  unlawful  (except  in  so  far  as  it  might 
be  permitted  by  statute)  to  express  or  to  teach  religious  opinions 
contrary  to  those  of  the  established  church ;  and  a  fortiori  to  ex- 
press or  teach  anti-Christian  doctrine.  But,  long  before  the  end 
of  this  period,  the  manner  in  which  these  principles  were  safe- 
guarded was  anything  but  mediaeval  ;  for  their  maintenance  had 
passed  from  the  ecclesiastical  courts  to  the  ordinary  courts  of  law 
and  equity.  And  the  result  had  been  a  slight,  but  only  a  slight, 
weakening  of  their  rigidity. 

Throughout  this  period  it  fell  to  the  ordinary  courts  to  apply 
the  many  statutes  which  penalized  the  nonconformist,  whether 
Protestant  or  Roman  Catholic.  While  these  statutes  were  in 
force,  the  expression  of  these  opinions  was  not  only  illegal, 
but  in  many  cases  criminal ;  so  that  no  contract  or  trust,  which 
was  designed  to  help  the  propagation  of  these  opinions,  was 
lawful.  The  only  exception  made  to  this  legislation  were  the 
provisions  of  the  Toleration  Act  of  1689,1  in  favour  of  certain 
sects  of  Protestant  nonconformists.  With  this  Act  and  its  inter- 
pretation I  shall  deal  under  the  following  head.2 

During  the  earlier  half  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  courts 
of  common  law  were  assisted  by  the  ecclesiastical  courts,  and  more 
especially  by  the  court  of  High  Commission.3  All  these  courts 
exercised,  as  we  have  seen,  an  extensive  jurisdiction  over  heresies 
of  all  kinds  ;  and,  as  late  as  161 2,  in  the  case  of  Legate,  a  writ  of 
de  haeretico  comburendo  issued,  and  the  heretic  was  burned.4 
In  fact  in  161 8  in  Atwood's  Case,5  the  court  of  King's  Bench 
ruled  that  the  uttering  of  scandalous  words  against  the  established 

1  1  William  and  Mary  c.  18.  2  Below  410-411. 

3  For  this  court  see  vol.  i  605-611.  4  Vol.  i  618.  5  Cro.  Jac.  421. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        407 

religion,  was  certainly  not  a  matter  over  which  the  justices  of  the 
peace  had  jurisdiction,  and  inclined  to  the  view  that  such  a  case 
should  have  come  before  the  High  Commission.  In  Traskes  Case,1 
though  the  Star  Chamber  sentenced  the  accused  for  maintaining 
the  theses  that  the  Jewish  and  not  the  Christian  sabbath  should  be 
observed,  and  that  pork  should  be  avoided,  they  expressly  did  so 
because  the  preaching  of  these  opinions  tended  "to  sedition  and 
commotion,"  and  scandalized  the  king,  the  bishops  and  the  clergy. 
The  offence  of  holding  these  heretical  opinions,  they  held,  was 
"examinable  in  the  ecclesiastical  courts  and  not  here."2  We 
have  seen  that  the  High  Commission  was  abolished  in  1641  ;3  and 
that  it  was  not  restored  with  the  other  ecclesiastical  courts  at  the 
Restoration.4  We  have  seen,  too,  that  the  ecclesiastical  courts 
lost  in  1677  their  right  to  inflict  capital  punishment;  and  that 
after  that  date  their  jurisdiction  over  the  heretical  opinions  of  lay- 
men disappeared.5 

But,  during  the  latter  half  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  courts 
of  common  law  stepped  into  the  breach.  They  had  long  enforced 
the  statutes  against  religious  nonconformity.  They  now  took 
over  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Star  Chamber  as  a  '  censor  morum,'  and 
punished  gross  indecency,  ribaldry,  and  blasphemy  on  the  same 
principles  as  those  on  which  the  Star  Chamber  had  proceeded. 
They  also  took  over  some  part  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  ecclesi- 
astical courts,  and  punished  the  expression  of  infidel  opinions, 
both  on  the  ground  that  they  tended  to  sedition  and  commotion, 
and  on  the  ground  that  it  was  contrary  to  law  to  attack  the 
foundations  of  the  Christian  faith.  One  or  two  cases  of  the 
late  seventeenth  and  eighteenth  centuries  will  show  the  principles 
upon  which  they  proceeded. 

In  1663  Sedley  was  indicted  for  gross  indecency,  against  the 
king's  peace,  and  to  the  great  scandal  of  Christianity. 6  The  court 
of  King's  Bench  expressly  claimed  to  have  inherited  the  Star 
Chamber  jurisdiction  as  custos  morum,  and  also  to  punish  profane 
actions  which  were  wholly  contrary  to  Christianity.7  In  1676  the 
King's  Bench  laid  it  down  that  the  speaking  of  blasphemous  words 
was  criminal,  both  as  an  offence  against  religion,  and  as  an  offence 

1  (1618)  Hob.  236. 

2  "  Now  he  being  called  ore  tenus,  was  sentenced  to  fine  and  imprisonment,  not 
for  holding  those  opinions  (for  those  were  examinable  in  the  ecclesiastical  courts  and 
not  here)  but  for  making  of  conventicles  and  factions  by  that  means,  which  may  tend 
to  sedition  and  commotion,  and  for  scandalizing  the  King,  the  bishops,  and  the  clergy." 

3  Vol.  i  611 ;  vol.  vi  112,  135.  *  Vol.  i  611  ;  vol.  vi  113,  196. 
5  Vol.  i  618-619.  *  1  Sid.  168. 

7  "  Et  fuit  dit  a  luy  per  les  justices  que  coment  la  ne  fuit  a  eel  temps  ascun 
Star  Chamber,  uncore  ils  voil  fair  luy  de  scaver  que  cest  Court  est  custos  morum  de 
touts  les  subjects  le  Roy,  et  est  ore  haut  temps  de  punnier  tiels  profane  actions  fait 
encounter  tout  modesty,  queux  sont  cy  frequent,  sicome  nient  solement  Christianity," 
ibid. 


408  CRIME  AND  TORT 

against  the  state.1  The  state  and  religion  were  regarded  as  allies 
who  must  stand  together  to  preserve  the  social  order,  so  that  to 
speak  against  religion  was  as  much  an  offence  as  to  speak  against 
the  state.  "To  say,"  said  Hale,  "that  religion  is  a  cheat,  is  to 
dissolve  all  those  obligations  whereby  the  civil  societies  are  pre- 
served." "Christianity  is  parcel  of  the  laws  of  England;  and 
therefore  to  reproach  the  Christian  religion  is  to  speak  in  sub- 
version of  the  law."2  These  cases  were  followed.  In  1721 
a  person  was  indicted  for  a  libel  against  the  Trinity,3  and  it 
appears  that  he  was  convicted  and  sentenced.4  In  1729  a  per- 
son was  convicted  for  blasphemous  discourses  on  the  miracles, 
"and  the  court  declared  that  they  would  not  suffer  it  to  be  de- 
bated whether  to  write  against  Christianity  in  general  was  not  an 
offence  punishable  in  the  temporal  courts  at  common  law. " 5 
"Christianity,"  said  Raymond,  C.J.,6  "is  parcel  of  the  common 
law  of  England,  and  therefore  to  be  protected  by  it ;  now  what- 
ever strikes  at  the  very  root  of  Christianity,  tends  manifestly  to 
the  dissolution  of  civil  government,  and  so  was  the  opinion  of  my 
Lord  Hale  in  Taylor's  Case."  In  1763  there  was  another  con- 
viction for  a  blasphemous  libel.7 

Naturally  the  offences  thus  punished  took  different  forms. 
They  are  classified  by  Hawkins 8  as  blasphemies  against  God, 
profane  scoffing  at  Holy  Scripture,  impostures  in  religion,  open 
lewdness,  offences  of  a  like  nature  tending  to  subvert  all  religion 
or  morality,  and  seditious  words  in  derogation  of  the  established 
religion  tending  to  provoke  a  breach  of  the  peace.  Another 
offence  of  a  similar  kind,  that  of  apostasy,  was  made  the  subject 
of  a  special  statute,0  which,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  has  had  singularly 
little  effect ;  for  it  was  held  that  it  did  not  add  materially  to  the 
common  law ; 10  and  no  convictions  are  known  to  have  been  ob- 
tained for  its  breach.11  All  these  offences  depended  at  bottom  on 
the  underlying  idea  that  offences  against  the  Christian  religion 
must  be  treated  as  offences  against  the  law  of  the  land,  because 
Christianity,  being  a  principal  support  of  the  state  and  its  law, 
the  state  and  its    law   were   especially  bound    to    maintain    it.12 

I  Taylor's  Case,  1  Vent.  293.  "  Ibid.  3  R.  v.  Hall,  1  Str.  416. 

4  In  R.  v.  Curl  (1727)  1  Str.  at  p.  790,  it  was  stated  that  Hall  was  convicted  and 
was  then  in  custody. 

5  R.  v.  Woolston  2  Str.  834.  B  S.C.  FitzGibbon  at  p.  65. 
7  R.  v.  Annet,  1  W.  Bl.  395.                       8  P.C.  Bk.  1  c.  5. 

9  9  William  III.  c.  35. 

10  See  Attorney-General  v.  Pearson  (1817)  3  Mer.  at  pp.  406-408  per  Lord 
Eldon  C. 

II  See  Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society  [1917]  A.C.  at  p.  446,  per  Lord  Parker. 

12  "  This  is  grounded  upon  the  care  that  the  government  hath,  or  ought  to  have,  by 
the  constitution  of  the  government  itself,  of  the  Christian  religion,  which  I  conceive  is 
the  main  end  of  government.  The  profession  and  preservation  of  Christianity  is  of  so 
high  a  nature  that  of  itself  it  supersedes  all  law  :  if  any  law  be  made  against  any  point 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        409 

"  Christianity,"  says  Blackstone,  "  is  part  of  the  law  of  England  ; " 
and  therefore,  in  addition  to  the  laws  which  safeguarded  the 
position  of  the  established  church,  and  penalized  nonconformity 
with  it,  the  law  must  punish  such  offences  as  apostasy  and  blas- 
phemy.1 

And  this  conception  was  logically  followed  out  Because  any 
attempt  to  propagate  beliefs  inimical  to  Christianity  was  a 
criminal  offence,  a  trust  for  any  sect  which  professed  such  beliefs 
was  illegal  and  void.  In  1 684  a  trust  to  pay  a  sum  of  money  to 
ministers  ejected  for  nonconformity  was  declared  to  be  void  ; 2  and, 
in  the  case  of  De  Costa  v.  De  Pas  in  1744,3  Lord  Hardwicke 
refused  to  enforce  a  trust  for  the  "  maintenance  of  a  '  Jesiba,'  or 
assembly  for  daily  reading  the  Jewish  law,  and  for  advancing  and 
propagating  their  holy  religion."  °  The  intent  of  this  bequest,' 
he  said,  "  must  be  taken  to  be  in  contradiction  to  the  Christian 
religion,  which  is  a  part  of  the  law  of  the  land,  which  is  so  laid 
down  by  Lord  Hale  and  Lord  Raymond ;  and  it  undoubtedly  is 
so ;  for  the  constitution  and  policy  of  this  nation  is  founded 
thereon." 

It  is  true  that  common  law  doctrine  had  made  some  little 
progress  in  the  direction  of  toleration.  In  Calvin's  Case  Coke  had 
given  utterance  to  the  very  mediaeval  sentiment  that  all  infidels 
are  in  law  perpetual  enemies,  "  for  between  them,  as  with  the 
devils,  whose  subjects  they  be,  and  the  Christian,  there  is  per- 
petual hostility  and  can  be  no  peace."  4  But  this  idea  had  been 
repudiated  by  Littleton  in  Charles  I.'s  reign;5  and  it  was 
obviously  contrary  to  the  commercial  interests  of  a  country  which 
was  beginning  to  conduct  a  prosperous  trade  with  infidels.6     Then 

of  the  Christian  religion  that  law  is  ipso  facto  void,"  East  India  Co.  v.  Sandys  (1684) 
10  S.T.  at  pp.  374-375  per  Holt  arg. :  and  to  this  Treby,  who  argued  on  the  other  side, 
assented,  ibid  at  p.  392. 

1  Comm.  iv.  59. 

2  Attorney-General  v.  Baxter  1  Vem.  248 ;  the  decree  was  reversed  in  i68g,  2 
Vern.  105,  on  the  ground  that  it  was  a  good  charitable  trust  for  particular  persons  to 
be  selected  by  Baxter,  see  the  extract  from  Lord  Hardwicke's  notebook  cited  by  Lord 
Eldon  in  Moggridge  v.  Thackwell  (1803)  7  Ves.  at  p.  76. 

3  2  Swanst  487  note.  4  (1609)  7  Co.  Rep.  at  ff.  17a,  17b. 
5  1  Salk.  46. 

8  Thus  Treby,  in  his  argument  in  East  India  Co.  v.  Sandys  (1684)  10  S.T.  at 
pp.  391-392  says,  "if  this  perpetual  hostility  be  taken  in  a  political  and  proper  sense 
and  the  law  be  so,  it  destroys  the  licence  and  privilege  of  the  Company.  ...  I  must 
take  leave  to  say  that  this  notion  of  Christians  not  to  have  commerce  with  infidels  is  a 
conceit  absurd,  monkish,  fantastical,  and  fanatical.  'Tis  akin  to  Dominium  fundatur 
in  Gratia.  The  Indians  have  a  right  to  trade  here,  and  we  there,  and  this  is  a  right 
natural  and  human,  which  the  Christian  faith  doth  not  alter  "  ;  the  strictures  on  Coke's 
dictum  made  by  Willes,  C.J.,  in  Omichund  v.  Barker  (1744)  Willes  at  p.  542,  and  by  Lord 
Mansfield,  C.J.,  in  Campbell  v.  Hall  (1774)  20  S.T.  at  pp.  294,  323  are  well  known, 
and  illustrate  the  very  different  point  of  view  of  the  eighteenth  century;  note  also 
that  the  mercantile  reason  was  much  emphasized  in  Omichund  v.  Barker  at  p.  551, 
which  case  overruled  Coke's  statement,  Co.  Litt.  6b,  that  an  infidel  could  not  be  a 
witness ;  see  also  2  Swanst,  502  note, 


410  CRIME  AND  TORT 

again,  in  R.  v.  Woolston,  the  court  said  that,  though  to  write 
against  Christianity  in  general  was  an  offence,  "  they  did  not  intend 
to  include  disputes  between  learned  men  upon  particular  con- 
troverted points."1  We  shall  see,  too,  that  the  manner  in  which 
the  Toleration  Act  of  1689  was  interpreted,  is  evidence  of  the 
growth  of  a  more  tolerant  spirit.2  Still,  when  all  deductions  have 
been  made,  there  can  be  little  doubt  that,  during  this  period, 
Christianity  was  regarded  as  so  integral  a  part  of  the  law,  that 
any  attack  on  it  was  an  offence,  and  that  no  disposition  of 
property  designed  to  propagate  anti-Christian  views  would  be  up- 
held. That  this  was  then  the  law  was  almost  admitted  by  Lord 
Coleridge,  C.J.,  in  R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote?  in  which,  as  we  shall 
see,4  a  very  different  rule  of  law  was  laid  down.  No  doubt  he 
endeavours  to  explain  some  of  these  cases  away,  but,  as 
Stephen,  J.,  has  shown,  with  very  little  success.5  I  think  that 
Stephen  is  quite  right  in  asserting  that,  in  this  period,  the  judges, 
when  they  held  that  Christianity  was  part  of  the  law,  meant  to 
hold  that  it  was  "a  crime  either  to  deny  the  truth  of  the  funda- 
mental doctrines  of  the  Christian  religion,  or  to  hold  them  up  to 
ridicule  or  contempt."  6 

We  must  now  turn  to  the  history  of  the  way  in  which  this 
principle  was  gradually  undermined.  We  shall  see  that  the  first 
really  decisive  steps  in  this  direction  were  taken  by  the  Legislature  ; 
and  that  this  legislation  was  made  the  more  effectual  by  the  rapid 
growth  of  the  spirit  of  toleration  among  the  more  educated  classes 
during  the  eighteenth,  and  the  earlier  part  of  the  nineteenth, 
centuries. 

(2)  The  new  situation  created  by  the  repeal  or  modification  of 
the  legislation  against  religious  nonconformity. 

The  first  modification  of  the  legislation  against  religious  non- 
conformity was  the  Toleration  Act  of  1689.7  We  have  seen  that 
it  was  the  services  rendered  by  the  Protestant  nonconformists  to 
the  cause  of  the  Revolution,  which  secured  for  them  this  measure 
of  relief  from  the  disabilities  under  which  they  suffered.8     In  form 

1  (1729)  2  Str.  834.  2  Below  411. 

3"  Now  according  to  the  old  law,  or  the  dicta  of  the  judges  in  old  times,  the 
passages  would  undoubtedly  be  blasphemous  libels,  because  they  asperse  the  truth  of 
Christianity.  But  ...  I  think  that  these  old  cases  can  no  longer  be  taken  to  be  a 
statement  of  the  law  at  the  present  day,"  R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote  (1883)  15  Cox  C.C. 
at  pp.  234-235. 

4  Below  415. 

5  Fortnightly  Rev.  xli  289  sqq.;  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  470-476. 

"Fortnightly  Rev.  xli  293  ;  or  as  he  puts  it  at  pp.  293-294,  "the  theory  is  as 
plain  and  concise  as  possible ;  the  truth  of  some  of  the  fundamental  doctrines  of 
Christianity  is  essential  to  the  welfare  of  society ;  therefore  everyone  shall  be  punished 
who  denies,  reviles,  or  ridicules  them." 

7  1  William  and  Mary  c.  18.  8  Vol.  vi  200-201. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        411 

the  concessions  granted  by  the  Act  were  not  large.  It  simply,  as 
its  title  says,  "exempted  their  Majesties' Protestant  subjects  dis- 
senting from  the  Church  of  England  from  the  penalties  of  certain 
laws."  But,  as  a  necessary  consequence,  it  legalized  their  meet- 
ings for  worship,  provided  they  were  not  held  behind  locked 
doors ;  and  it  provided  penalties  for  those  who  disturbed  these 
meetings.  In  addition,  it  exempted  nonconformist  ministers  from 
jury  service,  and  service  in  certain  parochial  offices,  and  it  allowed 
Quakers  to  make  a  declaration  instead  of  taking  an  oath.  The 
Act  did  not  extend  either  to  Roman  Catholics  or  to  Unitarians. 
The  courts  interpreted  the  Act  liberally.  It  was  held  that  its 
effect  was  to  render  the  worship  of  the  sects  coming  within  the 
protection  of  the  Act  legal  for  all  purposes,1  so  that  a  trust  for 
the  maintenance  of  their  teaching  could  be  enforced  by  the  court, 
or,  in  a  suitable  case,  a  mandamus  could  issue  to  enforce  the  legal 
rights  of  a  minister  to  be  admitted  to  office.2 

No  further  statute  was  passed  to  legalize  the  worship  of  other 
Protestant  nonconformists  for  more  than  a  century.  In  1813  the 
Unitarians  were  given  the  same  privileges  as  had  been  accorded  to 
Protestant  nonconformists  by  the  Toleration  Act  of  1689  ;  and  so 
much  of  the  blasphemy  Act  of  1 698,  as  related  to  the  denial  of  the 
doctrine  of  the  Trinity,  was  repealed.3  But  Lord  Eldon  had  grave 
doubts  whether  this  Act  in  favour  of  the  Unitarians,  could  be  given 
the  same  extensive  interpretation  as  had  been  given  to  the  Act  of 
1689  in  favour  of  other  Protestant  nonconformists.  His  view  was 
that,  though  the  penalties  for  the  maintenance  of  these  opinions 
had  been  removed,  the  impugning  of  the  doctrine  of  the  Trinity 
was  still  "  an  offence  indictable  by  the  common  law  "  ;  so  that  a 
trust  to  propagate  such  doctrines  was  not  enforceable.4  In  this 
respect,  therefore,  a  trust  to  propagate  an  opinion  which  he  re- 
garded as  anti-Christian,  differed  from  a  trust  to  propagate  opinions 
which,  though  not  conformable  to  the  doctrines  of  the  Church  of 
England,  were  Christian.  But  this  restricted  view  of  the  Act  was 
dissented  from  in  1842.     The  judges,  in  the  opinions  which  they 


1  Attorney-General  v.  Pearson  (1817)  3  Mer.  at  pp.  409-410  per  Lord  Eldon  ;  it 
was  said  by  Lord  Mansfield  in  Evans's  Case  that  the  protecting  clauses  of  the  Tolera- 
tion Act  had  put  the  worship  of  the  Protestant  dissenter,  "not  merely  under  the 
connivance,  but  under  the  protection  of  the  law — have  established  it,"  cited  3  Mer. 
375  n. ;  for  Evans's  Case  see  App.  to  Furneaux's  letters  to  Blackstone,  and  Burn  Eccl. 
Law  ii  207  ;  see  also  the  passage  cited  by  Lord  Buckmaster  in  Bourne  v.  Keane  [1919] 
A.C.  at  pp.  866-867. 

2  R.  v.  Barker  (1762)  3  Burr.  1265. 

3  53  George  III.  c.  160. 

4  "  If  the  common  law  remains  yet  unaltered,  and  if  the  impugning  the  doctrine  of 
the  Trinity  be  an  offence  indictable  by  the  common  law,  it  is  quite  certain  that  I 
ought  not  to  execute  a  trust  the  object  of  which  is  illegal,"  Attorney-General  v.  Pearson 
(1817)  3  Mer.  at  p.  399. 


412  CRIME  AND  TORT 

gave  to  the  House  of  Lords  in  the  case  of  Shore  v.  Wilson}  held 
that  no  such  distinction  could  be  drawn  between  the  enforceability 
of  a  trust  for  the  propagation  of  Unitarian  tenets,  and  the  tenets 
of  any  other  sect  of  Protestant  nonconformists. 

In  1829  came  the  Roman  Catholic  Emancipation  Act,2  which 
relieved  Roman  Catholics  from  the  penalties  to  which  they  were 
still  subject,  allowed  them  to  sit  in  Parliament,  and  threw  open  to 
them  nearly  all  the  offices  of  state.  But  the  Act  contained  pro- 
visions for  the  suppression  of  Jesuits  and  other  religious  orders  of 
male  persons  belonging  to  the  Church  of  Rome ; 3  and  it  was  not 
considered  to  have  removed  the  illegality  of  charitable  trusts  for 
the  maintenance  of  the  Roman  Catholic  religion. 

In  1832  Roman  Catholics  were  put  on  the  same  footing  as 
Protestant  dissenters,  in  respect  to  "their  schools,  places  for 
religious  worship,  education,  and  charitable  purposes."4  But  the 
Act  was  not  to  affect  the  provisions  in  the  Act  of  1829  as  to  the 
suppression  of  Jesuits  and  other  religious  orders.5  It  was  held, 
however,  in  the  case  of  West  v.  Shuttleworth?  that  this  Act  did 
not  operate  to  validate  trusts  for  the  maintenance  of  superstitious 
purposes,  such  as  masses  for  the  dead.  In  fact,  the  Act  of  Ed- 
ward VI.,7  which,  in  suppressing  certain  superstitious  uses  then 
existing,  had  in  its  preamble  declared  the  illegality  of  such  uses, 
had  long  been  considered  as  having  had  somewhat  the  same  effect 
in  defining  what  was  a  superstitious  use,  as  the  preamble  of  the 
statute  of  160 1  8  had  in  defining  what  was  a  charitable  use.  This 
was  the  view  taken  of  the  preamble  to  the  Act  in  Adams  and 
Lambert's  Case  in  1602.0  It  was  followed  by  Duke  in  his  book  on 
Charitable  Uses,10  and, !  it  would  seem,  was  approved  as  established 

Jg  Cl.  and  Fin.  355  ;  at  p.  578  Tindal,  C.J.,  said,  "  that  Unitarian  preachers  and 
their  widows,  and  other  persons  professing  Unitarian  doctrines  are  capable  at  the 
present  day  of  receiving  the  benefit  of  charities.  ...  I  consider,  since  the  statute  of 
53  Geo.  3  c.  160,  all  distinction  between  Unitarians  and  other  Protestant  Dissenters 
as  to  this  purpose  is  by  law  taken  away." 

2  10  George  IV.  c.  7  ;  some  remission  of  the  laws  rendering  them  liable  to  penalties, 
and  a  permission  to  conduct  their  worship  under  strict  conditions,  had  been  granted  by 
31  George  III.  c.  32. 

3 10  George  IV.  c.  7  §§  28-37.  4  2,  3  William  IV.  c.  115. 

5  §  4.  6  (1835)  2  My.  and  K.  684. 

7 1  Edward  VI.  c.  14.  8  43  Elizabeth  c.  4  ;  vol.  iv  398. 

9  4  Co.  Rep.  at  ff.  106b,  109b,  nib,  113a,  all  cited  by  Lord  Wrenbury  in  Bourne  v. 
Keane  [1919]  A.C.  at  pp.  919-920 ;  all  through  this  case  it  is  assumed  that  uses,  such 
as  those  mentioned  in  the  preamble  to  this  statute,  are  superstitious. 

10  (1st  ed.)  106,  cited  by  Lord  Birkenhead  in  Bourne  v.  Keane  [1919]  A.C.  at  pp. 
843-844;  dealing  with  gifts  for  the  finding  or  maintenance  of  a  stipendiary  priest,  or 
for  the  maintenance  of  an  anniversary  or  obit,  or  of  any  light  or  lamp  in  any  church  or 
chapel,  or  any  like  intent,  he  says,  "  these  and  such  like  gifts  and  dispositions,  as  these 
are  not  to  be  accounted  charitable  uses  intended  by  the  purview  of  this  statute  (43 
Eliza,  c.  4),  but  superstitious  uses  intended  by  the  statute  of  1  Edw.  6  c.  14  "  ;  clearly 
the  idea  is  that  the  preamble  of  Edward  VI.  's  statute  is  to  be  taken  as  a  guide  to  what 
the  law  will  deem  a  superstitious  use,  just  as  the  preamble  of  Elizabeth's  statute  is  to 
be  taken  as  a  guide  to  what  it  will  deem  a  charitable  use ;  and  this  idea  is,  it  seems  to 
me,  implied  in  much  of  the  reasoning  in  Adams  and  Lambert's  Case. 


RELIGIOUS  NONCONFORMITY        413 

law  by  Lord  Hardwicke  in  De  Costa  v.  De  Pas,1  Having  regard 
to  these  authorities,  the  decision  in  West  v.  Shultleworth  -  was  in- 
evitable; and  it  was  followed  in  later  cases.3  In  i860,  when  the 
Legislature  gave  a  larger  measure  of  protection  to  Roman  Catholic 
charities,  it  assumed  that  trusts  for  superstitious  uses  were  still 
illegal ; 4  and  when  it  assumed  the  illegality  of  these  superstitious 
uses,  it  must  obviously  have  used  the  term  superstitious  use  in  the 
sense  in  which  it  had  been  judicially  interpreted.  The  result  of 
this  legislation,  therefore,  was  to  remove  all  penalties  and  dis- 
abilities affecting  Roman  Catholics,  and  to  legalize,  not  entirely, 
but  to  a  very  large  extent,  trusts  for  the  propagation  and  mainten- 
ance of  their  worship. 

In  18465  the  Jews  had  been  relieved  from  their  disabilities  by 
an  Act,  which  repealed  a  number  of  other  disabilities  and  penalties, 
which  earlier  legislation  had  imposed  on  various  classes  of  non- 
conformists. Moreover,  with  respect  to  their  schools,  places  for 
worship,  education,  and  charitable  purposes,  they  had  been  put  on 
the  same  footing  as  Protestant  nonconformists.6 

It  will  be  observed  that  this  legislation  contained  nothing 
whatever  affecting  the  position  of  the  atheist,  or  person  who  pro- 
fessed no  religious  belief;  and  the  curious  history  of  the  manner 
in  which  such  persons  were  gradually  allowed  on  all  occasions  to 
affirm  instead  of  taking  an  oath — a  history  which  in  its  later  stages 
is  connected  with  the  name  of  Bradlaugh — illustrates  the  reluctance 
of  a  Legislature,  which  was  still,  almost  unconsciously,  under  the 
influence  of  the  ideas  embodied  in  the  dictum  that  Christianity 
was  part  of  the  law,  to  make  any  concessions  to  them.7  Naturally, 
therefore,  during  the  earlier  part  of  the  nineteenth  century,  it  was 
still  held  that  those  who  denied  the  truth  of  all  religion,  including 
the  Christian  religion,  were  guilty  of  a  criminal  offence.  There  are 
a  series  of  such  cases  in  which  the  old  principle  was  laid  down  as 
good  law.8  In  fact,  as  late  as  1 841,  on  an  indictment  for  blasphem- 
ous libel,  Lord  Denman,  C.  J.,  told  the  jury  that,  "  if  they  thought 
that  the  libel  tended  to  question  or  cast  disgrace  upon  the  Old 
Testament  it  was  a  libel " ; 9  and,  in  the  decision  of  the  court  on  a 

1  "  The  objection  is,  that  this  is  a  superstitious  use,  and  so  that  the  bequest  must 
go  to  the  crown ;  but  in  answer  to  this  it  is  said,  that  that  can  only  be  in  cases  that  are 
within  the  statute  of  Edward  VI.  But  the  cases  have  gone  further,"  2  Swanst.  487 
note. 

2  (1835)  2  My.  and  K.  684. 

3  Attorney-General  v.  Fishmongers  Co.  (1841)  5  My.  and  Cr.  11  ;  Heath  v.  Chap- 
man (1854)  2  Dr.  417. 

4  23,  24  Victoria  c.  134  §1.  5g,  10  Victoria  c.  59.  6  §  2. 

7 See  Clarke  v.  Bradlaugh  (1881)  7  Q.B.D.  at  pp.  58-61  per  Lush,  J.,  for  a  good 
account  of  this  matter. 

8  R.  v.  Carlile  (1819)  1  S.T.N.S.  1390,  4  S.T.N.S.  1423  ;  R.  v.  Waddington  (1822) 
1  S.T.N.S.  1368-1369 ;  see  also  R.  v.  Moxon  (1841)  4  S.T.N.S.  694. 

9  R.  v.  Hetherington  5  Jurist  529-530. 


414  CRIME  AND  TORT 

motion  in  arrest  of  judgment,  substantially  the  old  principle,  that 
a  reflection  on  Christianity  in  general  is  indictable,  is  laid  down. 
It  followed  also  that  all  attempted  dispositions  of  property,  and 
other  transactions,  having  for  their  object  the  propagation  of  such 
opinions,  were  void.  Thus  in  1850,  in  the  case  of  Briggs  v. 
Hartley}  it  was  held  that  a  trust  which  contemplated  an  object 
inconsistent  with  Christianity  failed  ;  and  in  1 867,  in  the  case  of 
Coivan  v.  Milbourn,  it  was  held  that  a  contract  to  let  a  lecture 
room  for  an  anti-Christian  lecture  was  void  for  illegality.2 

But,  some  time  before  Cowan  v.  Milbourn  had  been  decided, 
the  feeling  in  favour  of  a  more  universal  tolerance,  which  was 
partly  the  cause  and  partly  the  effect  of  the  legislation  which  I 
have  just  described,  had  begun  to  react  upon  these  common  law 
doctrines. 

(3)  The  effect  of  the  new  situation  created  by  this  legislation 
upon  legal  doctrines  as  to  the  relation  between  law  and  religion. 

During  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  there  are 
indications  that  some  lawyers  were  beginning  to  be  of  opinion  that 
it  was  not  every  sort  of  questioning  of  the  truths  of  Christianity, 
which  would  make  the  questioner  criminally  liable.  As  early  as 
1729,  the  court  had  expressly  said  that  it  did  not  mean  to  assert 
that  theories  advanced  by  learned  men  upon  controversial  points, 
would  expose  those  who  held  them  to  liability,  provided  that 
Christianity  in  general  was  not  attacked  ; 3  and  both  Lord  Mans- 
field 4  and  Blackstone 5  had  maintained  that  the  mere  holding,  as 
distinct  from  the  propagation,  of  opinions  was  not  an  offence  by 
English  law.  We  have  seen  that  both  the  Star  Chamber  in  the 
earlier  part  of  the  seventeenth  century,6  and  the  common  law 
courts  in  the  later  part  of  that  century,7  had  assigned,  as  their 
reason  for  taking  cognizance  of  heretical  opinions,  the  fact  that 
they  tended  to  sedition  and  commotions ;  and  Blackstone  had 
emphasized  the  fact  that  blasphemy  consisted  in  "  profane  scoffing 
at  the  Holy  Scripture  or  exposing  it  to  contempt  and  ridicule."8 
Having  regard,  therefore,  to  the  larger  liberty  of  expressing 
opinions  secured  by  the  legislation  of  the  earlier  part  of  the  nine- 
teenth century,  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  that,  about  the  same 

1  19  L.J.  Ch.  416-417  ;  cf.  Murray  v.  Benbow  (1822)  4  S.T.N.S.  1409 — the  famous 
case  in  which  Lord  Eldon  refused  to  issue  an  injunction  to  restrain  the  publication 
of  a  pirated  copy  of  Byron's  Cain ;  see  also  the  authorities  cited  by  Lord  Finlay  in 
Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society  [1917]  A.C.  at  p.  430. 

2  L.R.  2  Ex.  230.  3  R.  v.  Woolston  2  Str.  834 ;  above  410. 

4 "  The  common  law  of  England,  which  is  only  common  reason  or  usage,  knows 
of  no  prosecution  for  mere  opinions,"  Evans  v.  The  Chamberlain  of  London,  Burn 
Eccl.  Law  ii  218,  cited  3  Mer.  375  note. 

5  Comm.  iv  49.  6  Above  407. 

7  Above  407-408.  8  Comm.  iv  59. 


RELIGIOUS  NON  CONFORMITY        415 

period,  it  began  to  be  thought  that  the  essence  of  the  offence  of 
blasphemy,  was  not  the  denial  of  the  truths  of  Christianity,  but 
their  denial  in  an  offensive  manner.  Starkie,  the  second  edition 
of  whose  book  on  libel  was  published  in  1830,  maintained,  in 
substance,  that  an  honest  denial  of  Christianity  was  not  blasphemy  ; 
and  that  the  essence  of  the  offence  was  "a  wilful  intention  to 
pervert  insult  and  mislead  others  by  means  of  licentious  and  con- 
tumelious abuse  applied  to  sacred  subjects,  or  by  wilful  misrepre- 
sentations or  artful  sophistry  calculated  to  mislead  the  ignorant  or 
unwary."1 

The  cases  already  cited  show  that  the  criminal  law  was  not 
for  some  time  expounded  in  this  way.  But  the  trend  of  public 
opinion  was  making  for  its  acceptance.  In  1842,  in  the  case 
of  Shore  v.  Wilson?  Erskine,  J.,  laid  it  down  that,  "  it  is  still 
blasphemy,  punishable  at  common  law,  scoffingly  or  irreverently 
to  ridicule  or  impugn  the  doctrines  of  the  Christian  faith,  and  no 
one  would  be  allowed  to  give  or  to  claim  any  pecuniary  encourage- 
ment for  such  purpose ;  yet  any  man  may,  without  subjecting 
himself  to  any  penal  consequences,  soberly  and  reverently  examine 
and  question  the  truth  of  those  doctrines,  which  have  been 
assumed  as  essential  to  it."  This  view  of  the  law  was  followed 
by  Coleridge,  J.,  in  R.  v.  Pooley  in  1857,3  and  by  his  son  Lord 
Coleridge,  C.J.,  in  R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote  in  1883.4  The 
correctness  of  this  statement  of  the  law  was  assailed  by  Stephen,  J.5 
That  it  was  not  a  correct  statement  of  the  law  of  England  in  the 
seventeenth,  or  even  the  eighteenth,  centuries,  I  think  he  proves ; 
and  indeed  the  historical  truth  of  Stephen  s  view  is,  as  we  have 
seen,  almost  admitted  by  Coleridge,  C.J.6  But  there  is  no  doubt 
that,  as  the  nineteenth  century  proceeded,   this   newer  view  of 

1 "  Though  as  a  matter  of  discretion  and  prudence,  it  might  be  better  to  leave  the 
discussion  of  such  matters  to  those  who,  from  their  education  and  habits,  are  most 
likely  to  form  correct  conclusions,  yet  it  cannot  be  doubted  that  any  man  has  a  right, 
not  merely  to  judge  for  himself,  on  such  subjects,  but  also  legally  speaking,  to  publish 
his  opinions  for  the  benefit  of  others.  .  .  .  The  law  visits  not  the  honest  errors,  but 
the  malice,  of  mankind.  A  wilful  intention  to  pervert,  insult,  and  mislead  others,  by 
means  of  licentious  and  contumelious  abuse  applied  to  sacred  subjects,  or  by  wilful 
misrepresentations,  or  artful  sophistry,  calculated  to  mislead  the  ignorant  or  unwary,  is 
the  criterion  and  test  of  guilt,"  Starkie,  Libel  (3rd  ed.)  559,  600,  cited  Stephen,  Fort- 
nightly Rev.  xli  311. 

2  g  CI.  and  Fin.  at  pp.  524-525 ;  and  he  had  laid  down  substantially  the  same  rule 
in  the  same  year  in  R.  v.  Holyoake  4  S.T.N.S.  1381. 

3  Stephen,  Fortnightly  Rev.  xli  311. 

4  15  Cox  C.C.  231 ;  "I  think  that  these  old  cases  can  no  longer  be  taken  to  be  a 
statement  of  the  law  at  the  present  day.  It  is  no  longer  true  in  the  sense  in  which  it 
was  true,  when  these  dicta  were  uttered,  that  Christianity  is  part  of  the  law  of  the 
land.  ...  To  asperse  the  truth  of  Christianity  cannot  per  se  be  sufficient  to  sustain  a 
criminal  prosecution  for  blasphemy,"  ibid  at  p.  235  ;  "  I  now  lay  it  down  as  law,  that, 
if  the  decencies  of  controversy  are  observed,  even  the  fundamentals  of  religion  may  be 
attacked,  without  the  writer  being  guilty  of  blasphemy,"  ibid  at  p.  238. 

5  Fortnightly  Rev.  xli  289  ;  H.C.L.  ii  474-476. 

6  Above  n.  4. 


416  CRIME  AND  TORT 

the  law  had  been  gathering  strength,  because  it  was  obviously 
so  much  more  in  accordance  with  men's  views  as  to  the  proper 
relation  between  law  and  religion  than  the  older  view1 — a  fact 
illustrated  by  the  settlement  in  1888  of  the  long  controversy  as  to 
the  right  of  the  atheist  to  affirm  instead  of  taking  an  oath.2  The 
law  laid  down  in  R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote  was  approved  by  the 
Court  of  Appeal  in  191 5  ; 3  and  the  principle  was  applied  by  the 
House  of  Lords  in  1917.4  It  is  therefore  now  indisputably  the 
law  of  England. 

It  did  not  follow,  however,  that,  because  a  reverend  denial  of 
Christianity  was  no  longer  a  criminal  offence,  the  law  would 
uphold  a  trust  or  a  contract  to  propagate  views  which  were 
directly  contrary  to  the  Christian  faith.  But  even  here  the 
former  rigid  attitude  of  the  law  was  weakening.  Judges  were 
astute  to  find  that  trusts  for  religious  purposes  were  not  anti- 
Christian  ; 5  and  at  length  in  191 7,  in  the  case  of  Bowman  v.  The 
Secular  Society^  it  was  held  that  the  propagation  of  such  views 
was  not  illegal  in  any  sense,  and  that  therefore  a  bequest  upon 
trust  for  a  company,  formed  to  propagate  these  views,  was  valid. 
The  cases  of  Briggs  v.  Hartley?  and  Cowan  v.  Milbourn 8  were 
overruled,  with  the  result  that  the  law  now  draws  no  distinction 
between  the  propagation  of  Christian,  non-Christian,  or  anti- 
Christian  opinions.  It  will  help  all  alike,  unless  it  can  be  shown 
that  they  advocate  practises  contrary  to  the  rules  of  English  Law. 
But  just  as  Stephen,  J.,  upheld  the  older  rules  as  against  the 
newer  law  laid  down  in  R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote,  so  in  Bowman  v. 
The  Secular  Society  Lord  Finlay  upheld  the  older  law  laid  down  in 
Briggs  v.  Hartley  and  Cowan  v.  Milbourn ;  and  in  both  cases 
these  advocates  of  the  older  law  were  solitary  protestants. 

The  legislation  of  the  nineteenth  century,  which  threw  open 
most  of  the  offices  of  state  to  persons  who  were  not  members  of 
the  established  church,  destroyed,  as  Blackstone  said  it  would 
destroy,9  the  logical  necessity  for  such  a  church.      In  like  manner 


1  "  Parliament,  the  supreme  authority  as  to  our  law  has  passed  Acts  which  render 
the  dicta  of  the  judges  in  former  times  no  longer  applicable.  And  it  is  no  disparage- 
ment to  their  authority  to  say  that  observations  which  were  made  under  one  state  of 
the  law  are  no  longer  applicable  under  a  different  state  of  things,"  R.  v.  Ramsay  and 
Foote  (1883)  15  Cox  C.C.  at  p.  235. 

2  51,  52  Victoria  c.  46  (The  Oaths  Act). 

3  Secular  Society  v.  Bowman  [19 15]  2  Ch.  at  pp.  462,  469-470. 

4  S.C.  on  appeal  [1917]  A.C.  406. 

5  See  Parr  v.  Clegg  (1861)  29  Beav.  589 ;  Thornton  v.  Howe  (1862)  31  Beav.  14  ; 
both  these  cases  were  decided  by  Lord  Romilly 

c  [1917]  A.C.  406.  '  (1850)  19  L.J.  Ch.  416. 

8  (1867)  L.R.  2  Ex.  230. 

9  "  If  every  sect  was  to  be  indulged  in  a  free  communion  of  civil  employments,  the 
idea  of  a  national  establishment  would  at  once  be  destroyed,  and  the  episcopal  church 
would  be  no  longer  the  church  of  England,"  Comm.  iv.  53. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        417 

the  decision  in  Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society  leaves  the  ecclesias- 
tical law  of  England  in  a  very  anomalous  position.  We  have  seen 
that,  as  late  as  1881,  it  was  described  by  Lord  Blackburn  as  part 
of  the  general  law  of  England.1  If  this  is  so,  it  would  seem  that 
the  situation,  in  which  the  rules  of  law  and  equity  sometimes 
found  themselves  before  the  Judicature  Acts,  is  again  reproduced. 
That  which  one  part  of  the  law  of  England  regards  as  illegal  is 
regarded  as  legal  and  enforced  by  the  other  part  But  the  effects 
of  this  decision  have  not  stopped  here.  As  we  shall  now  see,  the 
same  trend  of  public  opinion,  which  led  up  to  this  decision,  has 
encouraged  the  House  of  Lords  to  change  the  long  accepted 
interpretation  placed  upon  some  of  the  older  legislation  dealing 
with  Roman  Catholicism. 

(4)  The  effect  of  this  new  common  law  doctrine  upon  the  inter- 
pretation of  the  older  legislation. 

We  have  seen  that  the  legislation,  which  freed  the  Roman 
Catholics  from  their  disabilities,  did  not  wholly  emancipate  them.*2 
But  it  is  clear  that  some  of  the  judges  were  beginning  to  think 
that  these  restrictions  were  not  wholly  consistent  with  the  larger 
liberty  which  had  been  accorded  to  all  kinds  of  religious  and 
anti-religious  opinions.  In  i8603  and  18614  Lord  Romilly  ex- 
pressed some  doubts  as  to  the  correctness  of  the  law  laid  down  in 
West  v.  Shuttleworth  as  to  the  invalidity  of  superstitious  uses.  In 
1 91 4  the  restrictive  clauses  in  the  Act  of  1829,  directed  against 
monastic  orders,  were,  to  a  large  extent,  rendered  nugatory  by 
the  decision  of  Joyce,  J.,  in  the  case  of  In  re  Smith'0 — the  judge 
whose  decision  was  affirmed  by  the  House  of  Lords  in  the  case 
of  Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society.  Finally,  in  19 19,  practically 
the  whole  law  as  to  the  invalidity  of  superstitious  uses  was  swept 
away  by  the  decision  of  the  House  of  Lords  in  Bourne  v.  Keane* 
The  House  asserted  that  the  preamble  to  the  Chantries  Act  of 
Edward  VI.7  could  not  have  the  effect  which  is  still  accorded  to 
the  preamble  of  Elizabeth's  Act  of  1601  ;8  and  it  reversed  all  the 
cases  and  dicta  which  were  founded  ultimately  upon  the  view  that 
just  as  the  preamble  to  Elizabeth's  Act  is  a  guide  to  the  definition 
of  a  charitable  use,  so  the  preamble  to  Edward  VI. 's  Act  must  be 
taken  as  a  guide  to  the  definition  of  a  superstitious  use.  This  was 
a  bold  step.  When  the  House  of  Lords  in  19 16  was  reminded 
that  in   1888  it  had  reversed  a  decision  of  1849,  the  retort  was 

1  Mackonochie  v.  Lord  Penzance  (1881)  6  A.C.  at  p.  446,  cited  vol.  i  595. 

2  Above  412-413.  3  Re  Michel's  Trust  28  Beav.  at  p.  42. 

4  Re  BlundelFs  Trusts  30  Beav.  at  p.  362  ;  see  above  416  n.  5  for  Lord  Romilly's 
reluctance  to  find  anything  anti-Christian  in  an  otherwise  lawful  trust. 
*  [1914]  1  Ch.  937.  •  [1919]  A.C.  815. 

7  1  Edward  VI.  c.  14.  8  43  Elizabeth  c.  4  ;  vol  iv  398. 

VOL.  VIII.— 27 


418  CRIME  AND  TORT 

given  that  "  this  is  hardly  the  right  view  to  take  of  your  Lordship's 
judicial  functions  nowadays."1  But  in  this  case,  the  House,  as 
Lord  Wrenbury  pointed  out,  reversed  dicta  317  years  old,  a 
decision  84  years  old,2  and  a  rule  which,  in  191 7,  Lord  Parker 
had  regarded  as  a  settled  rule  of  law.3  But  Lord  Wrenbury 
in  this  case  took  the  position  of  solitary  protestant,  which 
Stephen,  J.,  took  in  relation  to  the  decision  in  R.  v.  Ramsay 
and  Foote,  and  Lord  Finlay  took  in  relation  to  the  decision  in 
Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society.  In  all  three  cases  the  movement 
of  public  opinion  in  favour  of  the  widest  toleration  was  sufficient 
to  overturn  the  principles  of  the  older  law.  Indeed,  it  was 
admitted  by  Lord  Birkenhead  that  it  was  the  same  public  policy 
as  that  underlying  the  judgment  in  Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society 
which  played  a  great  part  in  inducing  the  House  of  Lords  to  take 
the  greatest  liberty  which  it  has  ever  taken  with  established 
legal  principles.4  That  decision  is  thus  the  crowning  illustration 
of  the  manner  in  which  the  development  of  this  branch  of  the  law 
has  been  dominated  at  all  periods,  and  more  especially  in  its  later 
phases,  by  considerations  of  public  policy  and  by  the  force  of 
public  opinion. 

Thus  the  old  theories  upon  which  the  relation  of  State  to 
Church  were  based,  and,  consequently,  both  the  old  doctrine  as 
to  the  relation  of  English  law  to  Christianity,  and  the  technical 
rules  which  depended  on  that  doctrine,  have  been  swept  away. 
All  that  is  left  is  the  law  as  to  blasphemous  libel  as  restated  in 
R.  v.  Ramsay  and  Foote.  It  is  obvious  that  the  dominant  factor 
in  the  various  trains  of  technical  reasoning,  which  have  justified  the 
abolition  of  the  older  doctrines  of  law  and  equity,  and,  with  the 
assistance  of  the  Legislature,  have  impelled  them  in  the  direction 
of  universal  toleration,  has  been  the  influence  of  public  opinion  as 
to  the  proper  relation  of  the  state  and  its  law  to  religion.     Indeed, 

1  Admiralty  Commissioners  v.  S.S.  Amerika  [1917]  A.C.  at  p.  56,  per  Lord 
Sumner,  cited  vol.  iii  677  n.  2. 

a  [1919]  A.C.  at  p.  925  ;  he  might,  as  we  have  seen,  above  413,  have  added 
that  it  was  a  construction  in  which  apparently  Lord  Hardwicke  had  concurred. 

3  Bowman  v.  Secular  Society  [1917]  A.C.  at  p.  437. 

4  "  Unwilling  as  I  am  to  question  old  decisions,  I  shall  be  able,  if  my  view 
prevails,  to  reflect  that  your  Lordships  will  not  within  a  short  period  of  time  have 
pronounced  to  be  valid  legacies  given  for  the  purpose  of  denying  some  of  the 
fundamental  doctrines  of  the  Christian  religion,  and  have  held  to  be  invalid  a  bequest 
made  for  the  purpose  of  celebrating  the  central  sacrament  in  a  creed  which  commands 
the  assent  of  many  millions  of  our  Christian  fellow-countrymen.  In  the  second  place 
.  .  .  your  Lordships  will  have  the  satisfaction  of  deciding  that  the  law  of  England 
corresponds  upon  this  important  point  with  the  law  of  Ireland,  of  our  great  Dominions, 
and  of  the  United  States  of  America.  A  decision  based  .  .  .  upon  a  sound  view  of 
the  law  may  reasonably  appeal  to  these  two  powerful  considerations  of  policy  as 
against  the  admitted  impolicy  of  disturbing  old  conclusions,"  Bourne  v.  Keane  [1919] 
A.C.  at  p.  831. 


RELIGIOUS  NON-CONFORMITY        419 

I  think  that  it  would  be  true  to  say  that  in  no  branch  of  the  law 
has  this  influence  been  in  the  past  more  pronounced,  and  that  it 
still  continues,  and  will  continue,  to  exercise  at  least  an  equal 
influence  in  the  future.  In  the  past  that  influence  has  been  all  in 
the  direction  of  a  greater  liberty  and  a  fuller  toleration,  until  in 
our  own  days,  complete  liberty  and  full  toleration  have  been 
attained.  No  doubt  the  use  made  of  this  complete  liberty  and 
full  toleration  will  largely  determine  the  future  trend  of  public 
opinion ;  for  it  is  the  fact  that  this  gradually  extending  liberty  has 
not  in  the  past  proved  dangerous  to  the  safety  of  the  state,  that 
has  made  for  its  final  victory.  This  fact  is  not  unconnected  with 
that  growth  in  the  strength  of  the  state,  which  has  enabled  it  to 
be  more  generous  in  its  administration  of  the  criminal  law  than  in 
the  days  when  it  was  weak.1  But  if  this  liberty  should  be  misused 
so  as  to  endanger  the  safety  of  the  state,  there  can  be  little  doubt 
that  public  opinion  will  revert  again  to  its  older  attitude. 

The  principles  which  underlie  the  past  development  and  the 
probable  future  of  this  branch  of  the  law,  have  been  so  fully  and 
eloquently  summed  up  by  Lord  Sumner,  in  one  of  the  wisest 
pronouncements  that  have  ever  been  made  on  the  subject,  that  I 
shall  copy  his  words : 2  "  the  words,  as  well  as  the  acts,  which 
tend  to  endanger  society  differ  from  time  to  time  in  proportion 
as  society  is  stable  or  insecure  in  fact,  or  is  believed  by  its  reason- 
able members  to  be  open  to  assault.  In  the  present  day 
meetings  or  processions  are  held  lawful  which  a  hundred  and 
fifty  years  ago  would  have  been  deemed  seditious,  and  this  is  not 
because  the  law  is  weaker  or  has  changed,  but  because,  the  times 
having  changed,  society  is  stronger  than  before.  In  the  present 
day  reasonable  men  do  not  apprehend  the  dissolution  or  the 
downfall  of  society  because  religion  is  publicly  assailed  by 
methods  not  scandalous.  Whether  it  is  possible  that  in  the 
future  irreligious  attacks,  designed  to  undermine  fundamental  in- 
stitutions of  our  society,  may  come  to  be  criminal  in  themselves, 
as  constituting  a  public  danger,  is  a  matter  that  does  not  arise. 
The  fact  that  the  opinion  grounded  on  experience  has  moved  one 
way  does  not  in  law  preclude  the  possibility  of  its  moving  on 
fresh  experience  in  the  other ;  nor  does  it  bind  succeeding  genera- 
tions, when  conditions  have  again  changed.  After  all,  the  ques- 
tion whether  a  given  opinion  is  a  danger  to  society  is  a  question 
of  the  times,  and  is  a  question  of  fact.  I  desire  to  say  nothing 
which  would  limit  the  right  of  society  to  protect  itself  by  process 
of  law  from  the  dangers  of  the  moment,  whatever  that  right  may 
be,  but  only  to  say  that  experience  having  proved  dangers  once 

1  Vol.  v.  196. 

2  Bowman  v.  The  Secular  Society  [1917]  A.C.  at  pp.  466-467. 


420  CRIME  AND  TORT 

thought  real  to  be  now  negligible,  and  dangers  once  very  possibly 
imminent  to  have  now  passed  away,  there  is  nothing  in  the 
general  rules  as  to  blasphemy  and  irreligion,  as  known  to  the  law, 
which  prevents  us  from  varying  their  application  to  the  particular 
circumstances  of  our  time  in  accordance  with  that  experience." 

How  far  the  law  as  it  exists  to-day  is  likely  to  be  beneficial 
to  the  state  and  to  the  community  remains  to  be  seen.  Complete 
freedom  in  economic  relations  has  already  been  tried  and  found 
wanting.  It  is  at  least  doubtful  whether  it  will  be  any  more 
successful  in  respect  to  the  publication  of  opinions,  religious  or 
otherwise ;  and  it  may  well  be  that  in  religious  and  intellectual, 
as  in  economic  spheres,  we  shall,  as  Lord  Sumner  has  indicated, 
be  driven  to  revert  to  some  of  our  older  ideas.  It  is  not  unlikely 
that  those  who  have  abandoned  all  belief  in  the  authority  of  a 
God,  will  carry  their  scepticism  a  little  further,  and  begin  to 
question  the  authority  of  the  state.  The  Christianity  upon  which 
the  state  and  the  law  were  once  founded,  though  it  might  at  times 
unduly  magnify  the  authority  of  the  Church,  recognized  the  need 
for  the  secular  arm  of  the  state,  and  generally  supported  its 
authority.  But  what  of  the  various  non-Christian  or  anti-Christian 
sects  which  seek  to  take  its  place  ?  It  may  well  be  that  "false 
doctrine  heresy  and  schism  "  of  the  strictly  theological  variety, 
no  longer  connote,  as  they  often  did  connote  in  the  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth  centuries,  "sedition  privy  conspiracy  and  rebellion"  ; 
but  it  does  not  follow  that  the  state  can  afford  to  disregard  all 
kinds  of  false  doctrine.  It  does  not  follow  that  unlimited  licence 
to  propagate  views  and  theories  at  variance  with  broad  principles 
of  Christian  morality,  will  be  wholly  unproductive  of  political  effects. 
History  lends  no  countenance  to  such  a  conclusion  ;  and  the  proved 
efficacy  of  propaganda  supports  its  teaching.  In  fact,  it  is  not 
unlikely  that  Caesar,  now  that  he  has  deliberately  abandoned  the 
task  of  securing  for  God  the  things  that  are  God's,  will  find  con- 
siderably greater  difficulty  than  heretofore  in  securing  for  himself 
the  things  that  are  Caesar's.  If  that  result  should  follow  one  of 
two  courses  must  be  pursued.  Either  the  state  must  reassert  its 
authority  by  means  of  an  increase  in  the  severity  of  the  criminal 
law,  and  an  abridgment  of  the  liberty  to  express  immoral  or 
seditious  opinions ;  or  it  must  be  content  to  pursue  a  policy 
of  drift  and  concession  to  the  forces  opposed  to  it,  which  can  only 
lead  straight  back  to  a  set  of  political  conditions  which  will  bear 
no  small  resemblance  to  the  modified  anarchy  of  mediaeval  political 
society — without  the  redeeming  grace  of  the  spiritual  elements  in 
that  society,  which  sprang  from  the  deeply  rooted  religious  faith 
of  mediaeval  men. 


THE  PROCESS  OF  DIFFERENTIATION     421 

§  5.  Lines  of  Future  Development 

We  have  seen  that  the  mediaeval  law  of  crime  and  tort  was 
narrow.  It  was,  so  to  speak,  permeated  by  the  idea  of  trespass — 
by  the  idea,  that  is,  of  forcible  damage  to  person  or  property. 
At  the  end  of  the  mediaeval  period  it  was  only  just  beginning  to 
transcend  this  idea  through  the  instrumentality  of  the  writs  on  the 
case.  We  have  seen  that,  during  this  period,  the  criminal  law 
was  developed,  partly  by  the  Legislature,  and  partly  by  the  new 
ideas  introduced  by  the  Council  and  Star  Chamber ;  and  that  the 
law  of  tort  was  developed  partly  by  the  latter  agency,  and  partly 
by  a  great  expansion  of  the  action  on  the  case.  Consequently,  in 
the  criminal  law  many  new  treasons  and  felonies  were  created,  and 
the  modern  misdemeanour  made  its  appearance  ;  while  the  develop- 
ment of  the  law  of  tort  was  marked  by  the  growth  of  specific 
torts,  and,  as  we  shall  see  in  the  next  section,  by  large  changes  in 
and  additions  to  the  principles  of  liability.  With  some  of  these 
developments  I  have  already  dealt  in  the  preceding  sections  of 
this  chapter.  At  this  point  it  will  only  be  necessary,  firstly,  to 
sketch  briefly,  in  respect  to  certain  torts  not  already  dealt  with, 
the  manner  in  which  this  process  of  differentation  was  proceeding  ; 
and,  secondly,  to  indicate  some  of  its  effects  upon  the  growth  of 
the  law. 

The  Process  of  Differentiation 

(1)  Wrongs  to  the  person. 

During  this  period  we  can  see  the  beginnings  of  the  process 
which  will  differentiate  the  wrongs  of  assault,  battery,  and  false 
imprisonment,  and  create  the  specific  torts  known  by  these  names 
in  our  modern  law.  In  the  Middle  Ages  all  these  wrongs  were 
redressible  by  an  action  of  trespass ;  and  they  were  regarded 
simply  as  illustrations  of  the  multifarious  trespasses  to  the  person 
redressed  by  that  writ.  But  in  the  cases  decided  upon  writs 
brought  for  particular  trespasses,  and  upon  writs  on  the  case 
brought  for  wrongs  analogous  thereto,  we  can  see  that  the  law  is 
beginning  to  acquire  some  more  precise  rules  as  to  the  conditions 
under  which  these  wrongs  are  committed.  These  rules  are  the 
starting  points  of  the  further  developments  which  will  give  this 
branch  of  the  law  its  modern  shape. 

Assault  and  Battery. — As  early  as  the  fourteenth  century  it 
was  held  that  trespass  would  lie  for  an  attempted  battery  which  had 
failed  to  take  effect — for  instance  when  one  had  thrown  a  hatchet 
at    another   which   had    missed ; x    for   a   threatened    battery    if 

1  22  Ass.  99  pi.  60;  Belknappe's  argument  to  the  contrary  was  overruled  in  Y.B. 
40  Ed.  III.  Mich.  pi.  19 ;  and  in  Y.B.  45  Ed.  III.  Trin.  pi.  35  Belknappe  as  judge 
laid  down  the  law  in  this  sense;  Street,  Legal  Liability  i  10-11. 


422  CRIME  AND  TORT 

accompanied  by  actual  damage ; x  and  even  for  mere  threatening 
words  which  put  the  plaintiff  in  fear,  and  caused  him  damage.2  It 
was  held,  however,  in  the  case  of  Tuberville  v.  Savage,3  that  a 
present  threat  of  violence  was  needed  to  constitute  an  assault,  so 
that  where  one  put  his  hand  on  his  sword  and  said,  "  if  it  were 
not  assize  time  I  would  not  take  such  language  from  you,"  it  was 
no  assault ;  though  it  would  have  been  otherwise  if  he  had  held 
up  his  hand  in  a  threatening  manner  and  said  nothing.  In  this 
case  stress  was  laid  on  the  declared  intention  not  to  offer  violence  ; 
and  it  is  probably  because  no  intention  of  violence  can  be  certainly 
collected  from  general  words  of  threatening  or  abuse,  that  the  law 
has  abandoned  the  idea  that  such  words  can  be  accounted  as  an 
assault.4  It  was  the  same  emphasis  on  intention  which  has  given 
us  our  modern  definition  of  battery.  In  its  original  conception  it 
meant  the  infliction  of  physical  injury ; 5  and  we  have  seen  that  in 
the  Middle  Ages  an  action  lay  whether  it  was  committed  inten- 
tionally, negligently,  or  accidentally.6  But  it  was  held,  during 
this  period,  that  "  the  least  touching  of  another  in  anger "  is  a 
battery.7  This  at  once  introduces  the  question,  What  is  a  touch- 
ing in  anger?  and  this  question  can  only  be  answered  by  a 
reference  to  the  intent  of  the  party  who  touches  another.8  Thus 
it  was  held  in  Tubewille  v.  Savage  that  a  touching,  "done  in 
earnest  discourse  and  not  with  intent  of  violence  is  no  assault,"  and 
therefore  no  battery.9  But  this  rule  at  once  introduces  into  the 
offence  a  new  element — the  element  of  insult — which  may  justify 
heavy  damages  for  a  battery  which  inflicts  only  trifling  physical 
injury.10 

The  writ  of  trespass  for  assault  and  battery  remedied,  not 
only  violence  offered  immediately  to  the  plaintiffs  own  person, 
but    also    violence   offered    to    him    indirectly  through  violence 

1  Y.B.  45  Ed.  III.  Trin.  pi.  35. 

2  27  Ass.  134  pi.  n ;  Y.BB.  37  Hy.  VI.  Pasch.  pi.  8  at  p.  20b  per  Prisot,  C.J. ; 
7  Ed.  IV.  Hil.  pi.  31  per  Danby  and  Choke,  JJ. ;  the  same  rule  was  laid  down  in  Y.B. 
17  Ed.  IV  Trin.  pi.  2  p.  4b  by  Fairfax,  J.,  but  denied  by  Nedham,  J.,  and  Billing,  C.J. ; 
cp.  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  216  n.  (/>). 

3  (1669)  1  Mod.  3. 

4  Evely  v.  Stouly  (1615)  2  Buls.  at  p.  327  per  Dodderidge,  J. ;  Pollock,  Torts 
(12th  ed.)  216,  citing  '  the  Circuiteers'  (L.Q.R.  i  232) : — "  For  Meade's  Case  proves, 
or  my  Report's  in  fault,  that  singing  can't  be  reckoned  an  assault."  The  opinion  of 
Nedham,  J.,  and  Billing,  C.J.,  in  Y.B.  17  Ed.  IV.  Trin.  pi.  2  p.  4b  seems  to  be  in 
harmony  with  the  later  law. 

5  See  Street,  Legal  Liability  i  4-6.  6  Vol.  iii  376. 

7  Cole  v.  Turner  (1705)  6  Mod.  149  per  Holt,  C.J. 

8  "  The  factor  which  the  law  accepts  as  sufficient  to  justify  this  extension  is  found 
in  the  wrongful  or  hostile  intent  of  the  wrong-doer ;  in  his  malice,  as  the  element  is 
termed  in  other  departments  of  tort,"  Street,  op.  cit.  i  6. 

9  (1669)  2  Keb.  545  ;  "if  two  or  more  meet  in  a  narrow  passage,  and  without  any 
violence  or  design  of  harm,  the  one  touches  the  other  gently,  it  will  be  no  battery," 
Cole  v.  Turner  (1705)  6  Mod.  149  per  Holt,  C.J. 

10  Street,  op.  cit.  i  6 ;  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  213. 


THE  PROCESS  OF  DIFFERENTIATION     423 

or  threatened  violence  to  his  servants  and  tenants.1  As  Sir 
F.  Pollock  has  said,2  "  examples  of  this  kind  are  not  uncommon 
down  to  the  sixteenth  century  or  even  later  ;  we  find  in  the 
pleadings  considerable  variety  of  circumstance  which  may  be 
taken  as  expansion  or  specification  of  the  alia  enormia  regularly 
mentioned  in  the  conclusion  of  the  writ"  A  good  example  in 
this  period  is  the  case  of  Garret  v.  Taylor?  In  that  case  the 
defendant  had  threatened  the  plaintiffs  workmen  and  customers, 
so  that  they  desisted  from  working  for  or  trading  with  him.  It 
was  held  that  the  plaintiff  could  recover  damages  in  an  action  on 
the  case.  We  shall  see  that  the  principle  underlying  such  cases 
was  one  of  the  principles  contributing  to  developments  in  the  law 
of  tort,  which  were  called  for  by  the  growth  of  commerce  and 
industry  during  this  period — developments  which  have,  owing  to 
the  legislative  changes  of  the  nineteenth  century,  assumed  immense 
importance  in  modern  times.4 

False  Imprisonment. — "False  imprisonment,"  as  Mr.  Street 
says,5  "  was  one  of  the  first  trespasses  recognized  by  the  common 
law.  A  laying  of  violent  hands  upon  the  person,  and  an  actual 
forceful  deprivation  of  liberty,  is  the  element  undoubtedly  at  the 
root  of  liability  in  this  wrong.  In  other  words,  the  typical  original 
imprisonment  involved  a  battery."  But  even  in  mediaeval  times 
this  notion  was  extended.  In  Edward  Ill.'s  reign  Thorpe,  C.J., 
ruled  that,  ' '  there  can  be  said  to  be  an  imprisonment  in  all  cases 
where  a  man  is  arrested  by  force  and  against  his  will,  be  it  in  the 
high  street  or  elsewhere,  even  though  he  be  not  confined  in  a 
house."6  What  amount  of  restraint  will  amount  to  the  commis- 
sion of  the  tort  has  been  elaborated  in  the  later  cases.  It  was 
settled,  at  the  end  of  the  seventeenth  century,  that  the  restraint 
must  be  total,  so  that,  if  all  means  of  escape  are  not  blocked,  the 
tort  is  not  committed."  We  have  seen  that  some  aspects  of  the 
tort  shade  off  into  the  very  different  tort  of  malicious  prosecution  ; 
and  that  it  was  only  gradually  that  the  line  between  them  was 
clearly  drawn.8 

Besides  these  specific  wrongs  to  the  person  a  large  number  of 
other  unclassified  wrongs  were  redressed  by  the  action  on  the  case. 
In  all  these  cases  the  question  whether  or  not  a  tort  had  been 

1  F.N.B.  87  N.  *  Torts  (12th  ed.)  234,  and  references  there  cited. 

3  (162 1)  Cro.  Jac.  567.  *  Below  431. 

5  Op.  cit.  i  12-13,  citing  Bracton's  Note  Book  cases  314,  465. 

6  22  Ass.  104  pL  85. 

7  "  A  has  a  chamber  adjoining  to  the  chamber  of  B,  and  has  a  door  that  opens  into 
it,  by  which  there  is  a  passage  to  go  out ;  and  A  has  another  door  which  C  stops,  so 
that  A  cannot  go  out  by  that.  This  is  no  imprisonment  of  A  by  C  because  A  may  go 
out  by  the  door  in  the  chamber  of  B,  though  he  be  a  trespasser  by  doing  it.  But  A 
may  have  a  special  action  upon  his  case  against  C,"  Wright  v.  Wilson  (1699)  1  Ld. 
Raym.  739  per  Holt,  C.J.  8  Above  388. 


424  CRIME  AND  TORT 

committed  depended  upon  the  question  whether  the  defendant 
was  guilty  of  negligence.  But  of  the  growth  and  influence  of  this 
conception  I  shall  speak  in  the  following  section.1 

(2)    Wrongs  to  property. 

Of  wrongs  to  a  plaintiffs  right  to  the  possession  of  chattels  and 
land,  and  of  the  kinds  of  damage  to  property  redressible  by  the 
various  writs  of  trespass,  I  have  already  spoken.2  As  in  the  case 
of  wrongs  to  the  person,  a  number  of  other  unclassified  wrongs  to 
property  were  redressed  by  the  action  on  the  case,  if  the  defendant 
had  acted  negligently.3  I  have  also  said  something  of  the  develop- 
ment of  the  scope  of  nuisance  by  means  of  action  on  the  case.4 
At  this  point  it  will  only  be  necessary  to  call  attention  to  two 
other  aspects  of  the  law  as  to  nuisance,  which  have  given  rise  to 
important  bodies  of  rules  in  the  modern  law  of  tort. 

(i)  It  was  recognized,  certainly  by  the  beginning  of  the  six- 
teenth century,  that  a  nuisance  might  either  be  public  and  remedi- 
able by  indictment,  or  private  and  remediable  by  action  on  the  case 
at  the  suit  of  the  person  damaged  thereby.  But  the  question 
whether,  and  under  what  conditions,  a  person  damaged  by  a  public 
nuisance,  could  sue  for  damages,  remained  somewhat  debateable 
down  to  the  close  of  this  period.  It  had  been  laid  down  by  Fitz- 
herbert  in  1 536  s  that  an  action  would  lie  for  a  public  nuisance,  if 
the  plaintiff  could  show  that  he  had  suffered  special  damage  over 
and  above  the  ordinary  damage  caused  to  the  public  at  large  by 
the  nuisance.  "If  one  makes  a  ditch  across  the  highway,  and  I 
come  riding  in  my  way  by  night,  and  I  and  my  horse  are  thrown 
into  the  ditch,  so  that  I  suffer  great  damage  ...  in  this  case  I 
shall  have  an  action  against  him  who  made  the  ditch  across  the 
way,  because  I  am  more  damaged  by  this  than  any  other."  But 
Baldwin,  C.J.,  dissented.  He  considered  that  any  stoppage  of 
the  highway  was  simply  a  public  nuisance,  and  punishable  only 
by  indictment ;  °  and  in  this  divergence  of  opinion  we  can  see  the 
beginnings  of  long  standing  doubts  upon  this  matter.  Though 
Fitzherbert's  view  was  accepted,7  differences  of  opinion  arose  in 
the  seventeenth  century  as  to  what  could  be  considered  to  be  suf- 
ficiently special  damage  to  entitle  a  plaintiff  to  sue.      Holt,  C.J., 

1  Below  449-458.  2  Vol.  vii  57  seqq.,  402  seqq.  3  Below  458. 

"Vol.  iii  11,  28;  vol.  vii  328-331,  340-341.  5Y.B.  27  Hy.  VIII.  Mich.  pi.  10. 

6,1  Semble  que  cest  accion  ne  gist  pur  le  pleintiff  sur  l'estoppel  de  haut  chemin, 
car  le  Roy  ad  le  punition  de  cela,  et  il  est  present  en  le  Leet,  et  la  il  sera  redresse  : 
pur  ce  que  il  est  common  nuisance  a  touts  liges  le  Roy,  et  donquesn'est  reason  que  un 
private  particulier  person  aura  accion  sur  cela;  car  per  memele  reason  que  l'un  person 
aura  accion  pur  cela,  per  meme  le  reason  chescun  aura  sur  cela,  et  donques  il  sera 
puni  C  fois  pur  meme  le  cause,"  ibid. 

7  Williams's  Case  (1595)  5  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  73a  ;  Fowler  v.  Sanders  (1618)  Cro.  Jac. 
446. 


THE  PROCESS  OF  DIFFERENTIATION     425 

and  Rokeby,  J.,  ruled  that  the  plaintiff  must  be  prepared  to  show 
a  damage  to  himself  directly  arising  from  the  nuisance,  over  and 
above  that  suffered  by  the  public  ; x  so  that,  if,  for  instance,  through 
a  stoppage  in  a  road,  a  man  lost  a  valuable  piece  of  business  by 
his  late  arrival,  such  damage  could  not  be  recovered.  The  delay 
in  the  journey  was  no  more  than  was  suffered  by  the  rest  of  the 
public,  and  the  loss  of  the  business  was  too  remote.2  But  other 
judges  were  of  opinion  that  such  consequential  damage  was  not  too 
remote,  and  could  be  recovered.3  This  difference  of  opinion  has 
lasted  down  to  our  own  days,  and  has  given  rise  to  judgments  in 
the  House  of  Lcrds  which  are  not  easily  reconcilable.4 

(ii)  So  soon  as  the  application  of  the  action  on  the  case  to 
remedy  a  nuisance  had  begun  to  widen  the  conception  of  a  nuisance, 
the  difficulty  arose  of  drawing  the  line  between  those  species  of 
damage  which  are  absque  injuria,  because  they  are  only  the  neces- 
sary result  of  the  legitimate  user  of  a  man's  property,  and  those 
species  of  damage  which  will  support  an  action,  because  they  are 
the  result  of  an  improper  or  excessive  user  of  that  property.3  As 
early  as  1410  this  difficulty  arose  in  the  Gloucester  Grammar 
School  Case.0  The  masters  of  an  ancient  grammar  school  sued 
the  defendant  who  had  set  up  a  rival  school,  and  had,  by  his  com- 
petition, lowered  the  fees  which  they  were  formerly  able  to  charge. 
It  was  held  that,  though  there  would  have  been  a  good  cause  of 
action  if  the  profits  of  an  incorporeal  hereditament,  such  as  a 
franchise  of  fair  ferry  or  mill,  were  disturbed  by  the  setting  up  of 
a  rival  fair  ferry  or  mill,  in  the  absence  of  such  a  franchise,  no 
action  lay  for  damage  occasioned  by  legitimate  competition."     This 

1 "  The  plaintiff  could  not  have  an  action  for  stopping  of  this  way,  because  his 
coal  mine  was  near  it ;  for  though  it  is  a  convenience  to  him,  yet  the  situaticn  does 
not  give  him  any  greater  right  to  the  way  than  any  other  of  the  king's  subjects  .  .  . 
the  case  of  27  H.  8,  27  is  no  authority  for  this  action ;  for  there  Baldwin,  Chief  Justice, 
was  of  opinion  against  the  action,  and  his  opinion  has  been  held  law  ever  since,"  Iveson 
v.  Moore  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  pp.  492,  493. 

2  "  If  a  highway  is  so  stopped  that  a  man  is  delayed  in  his  journey  a  little  while, 
and  by  reason  thereof  he  is  damnified,  or  some  important  affair  neglected  ;  this  is  not 
such  a  special  damage  for  which  an  action  on  the  case  will  lie ;  but  a  particular  damage 
to  maintain  this  action  ought  to  be  direct  and  not  consequential ;  as  for  instance,  the 
loss  of  his  horse,  or  by  some  corporal  hurt,  in  falling  into  a  trench  in  the  highway," 
Paine  v.  Partrich  (1692)  Carth.  at  p.  194  per  Holt,  C.J. 

3  Iveson  v.  Moore  (1700)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  pp.  489,  491  per  Gould  and  Turton,  JJ., 
with  whom,  alter  a  fresh  argument  at  Serjeants'  Inn,  the  other  judges  agreed,  ibid  at 
P-  495- 

4Ricket  v.  Metropolitan  Rly.  Co.  (1867)  L.R.  2  H.  of  L.  175;  Lyon  v.  Fish- 
mongers Co.  (1876)  1  A.C.  662  ;  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  410  n.  /. 

5  "  Hankford.  Dampnum  puit  estre  absque  injuria,  coment  si  j'ay  un  molyn,  et 
mon  vicine  leve  un  auter  molyn,  peront  le  profite  de  mon  molyn  est  diminish,  j'averai 
nul  action  vers  luy,  uncore  il  est  damage  a  moy  quod  Thirning  concessit,"  Y.B. 
n  Hy.  IV.  Hil.  pi.  21. 

■ Ibid 

7  "  Nient  semble,  pur  ceo  que  in  vostre  cas  vous  avez  frank  tenement  et  enherit- 
ance  en  le  Market,  mes  icy  le  plaintiff  ont  nul  estate  en  le  School  mastership  etc.,  mes 
pur  le  temps  non  certein,  et  il  sera  encounter  reason,  que  un  Master  sera  disturbe  a 


426  CRIME  AND  TORT 

was  quite  in  harmony  with  the  principle  recognized  by  the  common 
law  that,  except  as  restrained  by  rules  of  the  statute  or  common 
law,  trade  ought  to  be  free.1  The  principle  was  restated  by  Holt, 
C.J.,  in  Keeble  v.  Hickeringill ;2  but  with  the  qualification  that,  if 
violent  or  other  illegal  means  were  used  by  the  defendant  to  further 
his  interests  at  the  expense  of  the  plaintiff,  an  action  would  lie.3 
We  shall  see  that  the  application  of  this  principle  has,  like  the 
application  of  the  principle  that  trespass  or  case  will  lie  if  a  man 
is  damaged  by  menaces  to  his  tenants  or  servants,4  helped  to  de- 
velop a  very  important  branch  of  the  law  of  tort  in  modern  times.5 
The  only  other  important  wrong  to  property  which  need  here 
be  mentioned  is  the  tort  of  deceit.  We  have  seen  that  in  the 
Middle  Ages  its  scope  was  very  narrow,  but  that  it  was  widened 
by  the  application  to  it  of  the  action  on  the  case.6  We  have  seen 
that  this  action  on  the  case  for  a  deceit  was  applied  chiefly  to 
deceits  in  the  performance  of  certain  contracts,  and  that  it  played 
some  part  in  the  development  of  the  action  of  assumpsit.7  The 
earliest  development  of  deceit  was  therefore  in  connection  with 
contracts.8  As  deceit  on  the  case  could  be  brought,  either  for  the 
breach  of  an  express  warranty,  or  for  damage  occasioned  by  a 
statement  known  to  the  maker  to  be  false,  it  was  perhaps  natural 
that  the  conception  of  deceit  as  an  independent  tort,  consisting  in 
making  a  false  statement  with  knowledge  of  its  falsity  to  the 
damage  of  another,  did  not  readily  emerge.  But  we  have  seen 
that  the  conception  of  deceit  was,  during  this  period,  being 
rendered  more  precise  by  cases  turning  mainly  upon  the  contract 
of  sale ; 9  and  it  was  the  analysis  of  the  nature  of  deceit  in  these 
cases  which  helped  the  courts  in  1789,  in  the  case  of  Pasley  v. 
Freeman™  to  allow  an  action  in  tort  for  a  false  and  fraudulent 
statement  which  caused  damage  to  another,11  though  there  was  no 
contractual  relation  between  the  deceiver  and  the  person  deceived.12 

tenir  Schole  ou  luy  pleist,  sinon  que  le  fuit  en  cas  ou  un  University  fuit  corporate,  et 
Escholes  fondus  sur  ancient  temps,  et  en  case  d'un  molyn  (comme  jeo  disoy  avant)  si 
mon  vicine  levy  un  molyn,  auters  que  soloient  moulder  a  mon  molyn,  alent  a  Tauter 
molyn,  peront  mon  tolne  est  amenus,  pur  eel  cause  jeo  n'avera  my  action,"  Y.B. 
11  Hy.  IV.  Hil.  pi.  21  per  Hankford,  J. ;  "  et  l'opinion  del  Court  fuit  que  le  briefe  ne 
gist  my." 

1  Vol.  iv.  350. 

2  (1707)  11  Mod.  74,  130 ;  3  Salk.  9;  Holt,  14,  17,  19  ;  the  best  report  of  Holt, 
C.J. 's  judgment  is  that  taken  from  his  MSS.  in  11  East  574  note. 

3  11  East  at  p.  576.  4  Above  423.  5  Below  431. 
6  Vol.  iii  407-408.                                  7  Ibid  429  and  n.  3. 

8  Ibid  407-408  ;  above  68.  »  Above  68-69.  10  (1789)  3  T.R.  51. 

11  Especially  the  broad  statement  of  Croke,  J.,  in  Baily  v.  Merrell  (1616)  3  Bulstr. 
at  p.  95  that  "  when  these  two  (fraud  and  damage)  do  concur  and  meet  together,  there, 
an  action  lieth,"  which  was  cited  by  Buller,  J.,  3  T.R.  at  p.  56,  and  by  Lord  Kenyon 
C.J.,  at  p.  64. 

12  Grose,  J.,  in  his  dissenting  judgment,  3  T.R.  at  p.  53,  said,  "  When  this 
was  first  argued  at  the  bar  ...  I  confess  I  thought  it  reasonable  that  the  action 
should  lie ;  but,  on  looking  into  the  old  books  for  cases  in  which  the  old  action  for 


r 

i 


THE  PROCESS  OF  DIFFERENTIATION     427 

(3)  Wrongs  to  domestic  relations. 
•  We  have  seen  that  in  the  Middle  Ages  the  peculiar  status  of 
wards,  infants,  wives,  and  servants  was  very  much  more  emphasized 
than  it  is  in  modern  law.1  We  have  seen  too  that  the  law  of 
property,  and  the  remedies  for  the  infringement  of  proprietary 
rights,  were  then  much  more  highly  developed  than  the  law  of 
contract,  and  the  remedies  for  breach  of  contract.'2  It  is  in  the 
period  when  these  ideas  were  predominant  that  the  law  relating  to 
these  kinds  of  wrongs  originated ;  and  all  through  the  history  of 
this  branch  of  the  law  they  have  made  their  influence  felt.  It  is 
this  fact  which  helps  to  account  for  the  unsatisfactory  state  of  some 
of  our  modern  rules. 

It  was  in  the  case  of  the  ward  who  was  heir  to  property  that 
the  proprietary  character  of  the  father's  or  guardian's  rights  were 
most  evident.  The  law  knew  a  writ  of  right  of  wardship ; 3  and 
it  very  early  adapted  the  writ  of  trespass  to  the  purpose  of  pro- 
tecting the  father's  or  the  guardian's  rights,  by  the  invention  of 
writs  for  the  ravishment  of  the  ward4  But  on  this  branch  of  the 
law  the  long  life  of  feudal  wardship,  and  the  great  value  of  the 
feudal  incident  of  marriage,  exercised  a  very  unfortunate  effect.0 
These  two  reasons  led  the  law  to  take  the  view  that  what  it 
protected  was  not  the  rights  of  the  parent  or  guardian  as  such, 
but  the  pecuniary  interest  which  the  parent  or  guardian  had  in 
the  marriage  of  his  heir.  It  followed,  therefore,  that  these 
remedies  were  not  available  for  the  abduction  of  any  child,  but 
only  for  the  abduction  of  a  child  who  was  an  heir.  Trespass,  it 
was  said  in  BarJiam  v.  Dennis,6  was  based  upon  a  proprietary 
interest,  and  in  a  son  or  daughter  a  father  had  no  property.  It 
was  only  available,  therefore,  to  protect  the  father's  proprietary 
interest  in  the  child's  marriage.7     For   this   reason   the   courts 

deceit  has  been  maintained  upon  the  false  affirmation  of  the  defendant,  I  have  changed 
my  opinion.  The  cases  on  this  head  are  brought  together  in  Bro.  tit.  Deceit  pi.  29, 
and  in  Fitz.  Abr.  I  have  likewise  looked  into  Danvers,  Kitchins,  and  Comyns,  and  1 
have  not  met  with  any  case  of  an  action  upon  a  false  affirmation,  except  against  a  party 
to  a  contract,  and  where  there  is  a  promise,  either  express  or  implied,  that  the  fact  is 
true  which  is  misrepresented." 

1  Vol.  iii  61-65,  215  (wards),  513-520  (infants),  520-533  (wives) ;  vol.  ii  460-463 
(servants). 

2  Ibid  355-356,  590.  3  Vol.  iii  17.  *  Ibid  17,  n.  1,  27. 

5  For  these  incidents  see  vol.  iii  61-66,  516.  6(i6oo)  Cro.  Eliza.  770. 

7  "  They  held  also  that  the  father  should  not  have  an  action  for  the  taking  of  any 
of  his  children  which  is  not  his  heir ;  and  that  is  by  reason  the  marriage  of  his  heir 
belongs  to  the  father  .  .  .  and  by  reason  of  this  loss  only  the  action  is  given  unto  him. 
.  .  .  But  for  the  taking  of  a  son  or  daughter  not  heir,  it  is  not  upon  the  same  reason,  and 
therefore  not  alike.  Here  the  father  hath  not  any  property  or  interest  in  the  daughter, 
which  the  law  accounts  may  be  taken  from  him,"  ibid  at  p.  770  ;  and  it  would  seem 
from  Gray  v.  Jefferies  (1587)  Cro.  Eliza.  55  that  this  remedy  was  only  available  when 
one  took  the  heir  and  married  him,  and  that  it  did  not  lie  for  the  loss  of  the  marriage 
for  any  other  reason,  or  for  injuries  to  the  child,  even  if  these  injuries  occasioned  the 
loss  of  the  marriage. 


428  CRIME  AND  TORT 

refused  to  recognize  that  the  father  had  the  same  kind  of  pro- 
prietary interest  in  his  child  as  he  had  in  his  servant1  or  his  wife.2 
The  result  was  that  his  interest  in  his  children  was  unprotected 
unless  the  child  happened  to  be  his  heir. 

One  of  the  judges,  indeed,  in  Barham  v.  Dennis  was  pre- 
pared to  take  a  more  liberal  view.  "The  father,"  said  Glan- 
ville,  J.,8  "hath  an  interest  in  every  one  of  his  children  to  educate 
them,  and  to  provide  for  them ;  and  he  hath  his  comfort  by 
them ;  wherefore  it  is  not  reasonable  that  any  should  take  them 
from  him,  and  to  do  him  such  an  injury,  but  that  he  should  have 
his  remedy  to  punish  it."  If  his  view  had  prevailed,  the  develop- 
ment of  this  branch  of  the  law  would  have  been  infinitely  more 
satisfactory.  As  it  did  not  prevail  the  law  was  driven  to  find  a 
remedy,  by  the  application  to  the  relation  of  parent  and  child,  of 
the  writ  provided  to  protect  the  relation  of  master  and  servant ; 
and  the  result  is,  as  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  pointed  out,  that  the 
development  of  the  law  has  been  "halting  and  one-sided."4  No 
doubt  this  device  helped  to  mitigate  the  hardship  of  the  law,  more 
especially  as  very  slight  acts  of  service  were,  in  later  law,  allowed 
to  be  sufficient  to  support  an  action.5  But  it  did  not  afford  a 
complete  remedy.  If,  for  instance,  the  child  was  too  young  to  be 
capable  of  service,  no  action  would  lie  for  injuries  to  it.6 

It  is  the  application  of  this  remedy  to  the  relation  of  parent 
and  child  which  is  still  used  to  give  a  remedy  to  a  parent  for  the 
commonest  and  most  flagrant  injury  to  his  rights  as  a  parent — the 
seduction  of  a  daughter.  It  would  seem  that  it  was  in  the  middle 
of  the  seventeenth  century  that  this  particular  application  of 
trespass  was  made.  In  1653,  in  the  case  of  Norton  v.  Jason,"  the 
plaintiff  brought  Case  forentering  his  house,  assaulting  his  daughter, 
and  getting  her  with  child.  Rolle,  C.J.,  gave  it  as  his  opinion  that, 
"although  the  daughter  cannot  have  an  action,  her  father  may, 
although  not  for  entering  into  his  house,  because  it  was  with  his 
leave,  nor  for  assaulting  his  daughter,  and  getting  her  with  child, 

1  Below  429.  2  Below  430. 

3  Cro.  Eliza,  at  p.  771.  4  Torts  (12  ed.)  226. 

5  In  Y.B.  22  Hy.  VI.  Mich.  pi.  49,  p.  31,  Newton,  C.J.,  lays  it  down  that  the 
relation  of  master  and  servant  cannot  be  presumed  from  the  relation  of  parent  and 
child — "  Si  jeo  porte  bref  de  Transgressio  quare  filinm  meum  et  haeredem  in  servicio 
meo  existentem  rapuit,  jeo  voile  bien  que  eel  bref  ne  vaut :  le  cause  est,  tout  soit  il 
[rapuit]  mon  fitz  et  heir,  il  n'est  enclude  en  ce  qu'il  est  mon  servant :  car  il  poit  servir  ou 
luy  plest"  ;  but  the  later  law  was  not  so  strict,  see  Weedon  v.  Timbrell  (1793)  5  T.R. 
at  p.  361  per  Ashurst,  J.  ;  cp.  Jones  v.  Brown  (1794)  1  Esp.  217 ;  Evans  v.  Walton 
(1867)  L.R.  2  CP.  at  p.  619  per  Bovill,  C.J. ;  in  the  last  named  case  Bovill,  C.J., 
says,  "  no  evidence  of  service  is  necessary  beyond  that  which  the  law  will  imply  as 
between  parent  and  child  " — a  view  of  the  law  quite  contrary  to  that  of  Newton,  C.J. 

6  Hall  v.  Hollander  (1825)  4  B.  and  C.  660 ;  but  Bayley,  ].,  thought  that  the 
father  might  have  Case  for  expenses  occasioned  by  the  child's  cure — a  view  which  has 
been  followed  in  the  United  States,  Street,  Legal  Liability  i  268  n.  7. 

1  Style  398. 


THE  PROCESS  OF  DIFFERENTIATION     429 

because  this  is  a  wrong  particularly  done  to  her,  yet  for  the  loss  of 
her  service  caused  by  this  he  may  have  an  action."  But,  he  added, 
"it  is  a  pretty  case  and  fit  to  be  argued."  There  is  another  case 
of  1664  in  which  the  plaintiff  brought,  not  Case,  but  trespass  quare 
clausum  fregit ; '  but  this  form  of  action  was  obviously  inapplicable, 
as  Rolle,  C.J.,  had  pointed  out,  if  the  entry  was  by  the  leave  and 
licence  of  the  father.  These  cases,  however,  made  it  clear  that 
the  principle  on  which  the  modern  action  for  seduction  rests  had 
been  reached.  It  was  laid  down  in  1664  that,  if  trespass  quare 
clausum  fregit  was  brought,  the  damages  were  not  limited  to  the 
loss  of  service,  but  that  the  injured  feelings  of  the  parent  could  be 
taken  into  account,  as  an  aggravation  of  the  wrong  done  in  break- 
ing his  close.2  If,  on  the  other  hand,  Case  was  brought  per  quod 
servitium  amisit,  the  injured  feelings  of  the  parent  could  be  con- 
sidered in  assessing  the  damages  for  loss  of  service.3 

The  courts  have  thus  done  their  best  to  adapt  this  remedy  to  the 
case  of  seduction.  But  the  incompleteness  of  the  remedy  is  here 
even  more  marked  than  in  other  cases  of  injuries  to  children.  For, 
in  the  oft-quoted  words  of  serjeant  Manning,4  "  the  quasi-fiction 
of  servitium  amisit  affords  protection  to  the  rich  man  whose 
daughter  occasionally  makes  his  tea,  and  leaves  without  redress  the 
poor  man  whose  child  is  sent  unprotected  to  earn  her  bread  amongst 
strangers." 

Of  the  remedies  given  by  the  law  for  the  abduction  of  a 
servant  I  have  already  spoken.5  We  have  seen  that  they  were 
supplemented  by  the  provisions  of  the  Statutes  of  Labourers. 
They  rested  at  bottom  on  the  idea  that  the  master  had  a  quasi- 
proprietary  interest  in  his  servant's  services ;  and  that  idea  is 
connected  with  ideas  as  to  the  status  of  a  servant,  which  originated 
in  the  rules  of  law  applicable  to  villein  status.  We  have  seen,  too, 
that  these  rules  were  made  the  foundation  in  Lumley  v.  Gye 6  of  an 
entirely  new  development  of  the  law.  In  that  case  the  real  right 
of  the  master  to  his  servant's  services,  was  in  effect  given  to  all 
persons  entitled  to  the  benefit  of  any  contract ;  for  it  was  laid 
down  that  it  is  an  actionable  wrong  to  interfere,  without  just  cause 
or  excuse,  with  any  existing  contractual  relation. 

The  same  principles  as  were  applied  to  the  servant  were  applied 

1  Sippora  v.  Basset  i  Sid.  225. 

s  "  Quant  ceo  est  ex  turpi  causa  come  fuit  icy,  l'accion  poet  esse  done  in  evidence 
sur  tiel  general  declaration  south  les  parolles  (alia  enormia),  et  le  reason  est,  quia  le  ley 
ne  voet  compell  le  party  de  monstre  ceo  de  record.  Mes  en  touts  auter  cases  de  trespass 
le  special  matter  pur  que  damages  serra  done  doet  estre  plead,"  1  Sid.  225  ;  cp. 
Russell  v.  Corne  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  1032  per  Holt,  C.J. 

3  Bennett  v.  Allcott  (1787)  2  T.R.  at  pp.  167-168  per  Buller,  J. 

4  Note  to  Grinnell  v.  Wells  (1844)  7  M.  and  Gr.  at  p.  1044. 

5  Vol.  ii  462-463  ;  vol.  iv  383-385. 

8  (1853)  2  E.  and  B.  216  ;  vol.  iv  384-385. 


430  CRIME  AND  TORT 

to  the  wife.  The  husband's  interest  in  his  wife's  consortium, 
unlike  the  parent's  interest  in  the  consortium  of  his  children,  was 
considered  to  be  sufficiently  proprietary  to  support  an  action  of 
trespass.1  This  is  quite  distinct  from  the  right  which  the  husband 
had,  jointly  with  his  wife,  to  sue  for  wrongs  committed  against 
her.2  The  latter  right  depended  upon  the  incapacity  of  the  wife 
to  sue  in  her  own  name.3  It  was  the  incapacity  of  the  wife  to 
consent,  which  was  the  principle  upon  which  the  husband  was 
allowed  to  bring  the  particular  form  of  the  action  of  trespass  or 
action  on  the  case,  known  as  the  action  of  criminal  conversation, 
against  one  who  had  committed  adultery  with  his  wife.4 

(4)    Wrongs  connected  with  commerce  and  industry. 

Certain  of  the  wrongs  with  which  I  have  dealt  in  this  and 
preceding  chapters  bear  witness  to  the  growing  importance  of 
commerce  and  industry.  Some  aspects  of  the  law  of  defamation, 
of  malicious  abuse  of  the  process  of  the  courts,  and  of  nuisance, 
the  development  of  the  conception  of  deceit,  and  the  development 
of  the  idea  of  conversion — all  afford  illustrations.  In  addition, 
there  is  a  solitary  case  of  1580  or  1595,  in  which  an  action  of 
deceit  was  maintained  for  counterfeiting  another's  trade  mark.6 
But  much  the  most  important  instance  of  this  influence  on  the  law 
of  tort  is  the  beginning,  at  the  close  of  this  period,  of  the  modern 
doctrine  of  employer's  liability,  with  the  history  of  which  I  shall 
deal  in  the  following  section.0  Indeed,  if  we  except  this  doctrine, 
it  may  I  think  be  said  that  the  growth  of  industry  and  commerce 
has  not,  during  this  period,  exercised  so  great  an  influence  on  the 
law  of  tort  as  might  have  been  expected.  The  explanation  of  this 
phenomenon  is,  it  seems  to  me,  somewhat  as  follows  : — 

We  have  seen  that  during  the  whole  of  this  period  all  branches 
of  commerce  and  industry  were  minutely  regulated  by  the 
Legislature.7  Wages  were  in  theory  fixed  by  the  justices;  and 
combinations  to  alter  the  rates  of  wages  thus  fixed  were  illegal. 

1  Guy  v.  Livesey  (1619)  Cro.  Jac.  501 ;  Hyde  v.  Scyssor  (1620)  ibid  538. 

2  Hyde  v.  Scyssor  (1620)  Cro.  Jac.  538 ;  Russell  v.  Corne  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym. 
1032. 

3  Vol.  iii  526  ;  cp.  vol.  v  315. 

4  See  Galizard  v.  Rigault  (1702)  2  Salk.  552,  where  the  right  to  bring  this  action  is 
assumed  by  Holt,  C.J. ;  Street,  Legal  Liability  i  264  ;  as  Mr.  Street  has  pointed  out, 
ibid  269  n.  1,  "  the  idea  in  allowing  trespass  for  assault  and  battery  to  be  used  in  an 
action  for  seduction  is  that  the  girl's  consent  to  the  act  of  intercourse  is  irrelevant  as 
against  her  father,  just  as  the  consent  of  the  wife  is  irrelevant  as  against  her  husband, 
in  an  action  for  criminal  conversation  " ;  cp.  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  227  n.  i,  and 
228  n.  /. 

5  Cited  by  Dodderidge,  J.,  in  Southern  v.  How  Popham  144,  as  decided  22  Eliza ; 
but  in  Cro.  Jac.  471  it  is  said  to  be  decided  33  Eliza. ;  as  Mr.  Street  has  pointed  out, 
op.  cit.  i  418-419,  it  was  not  till  the  eighteenth  century  that  this  branch  of  the  law 
began  to  develop. 

6  Below  472-482.  7  Vol.  iv  314-407  ;  vol.  vi  313-360. 


EFFECTS  OF  THESE  DEVELOPMENTS     431 

Forestalling  and  regrating  were  offences  known  to  the  law.  The 
corn  laws  tended  to  keep  uniform  the  price  of  corn.  There  were 
many  regulations  and  restrictions  both  as  to  apprenticeship  and 
modes  of  manufacture.  The  difficulties  placed  by  the  Legislature 
on  the  assumption  of  corporate  form,1  tended  to  prevent  the 
formation  of  large  combines  of  manufacturers.  In  addition,  in 
certain  localities  there  still  existed  restrictions  imposed  by  local 
bye-laws,  under  the  authority  of  powers  conferred  by  mediaeval 
charters.  When,  in  the  course  of  the  nineteenth  century,  nearly 
all  the  restrictions  imposed  by  these  multifarious  laws  were  swept 
away  under  the  influence  of  the  doctrine  of  laissez  faire,  a  number 
of  new  problems  were  set  to  the  law  of  crime  and  tort  We  have 
seen  that  one,  and  perhaps  the  most  important  of  these  problems, 
arose  in  connection  with  the  crime  and  the  tort  of  conspiracy.2 
But  the  same  causes  which  led  to  the  growth  of  this  branch  of  the 
law  of  tort,  led  also  to  the  growth  of  other  branches.  The 
principle  of  cases  like  Garret  v.  Taylor*  and  more  especially  of 
Keeble  v.  Hickeringill,*1  and  the  exact  definition  of  the  new  tort 
resulting  from  the  decision  in  Lumley  v.  Gye*  all  assumed  great 
importance  in  cases  which  turned  on  the  legality  of  certain 
activities  of  Trade  Unions  of  employes  and  combinations  of  em- 
ployers. Indeed,  the  fact  that  the  common  law  could,  from  the 
basis  of  the  principles  contained  in  the  Year  Books  and  cases  of 
this  period,  construct  a  body  of  law  which  was  fitted  to  regulate 
the  new  industrial  problems,  to  which  the  era  of  laissez  faire  had 
given  rise,  is  perhaps  the  strongest  illustration,  in  modern  times, 
of  the  adaptability,  and  of  the  practical  character  of  the  principles 
evolved  by  a  system  of  case  law. 

The  Effects  of  these  Developments  on  the  Growth  of  the  Law 

We  can,  I  think,  distinguish  three  important  effects  of  these 
developments  on  the  growth  of  the  law. 

Firstly,  the  development  of  the  substantive  law  in  and  through 
the  forms  of  action,  made  it  sometimes  unreasonable,  and  some- 
times excessively  technical.  The  manner  in  which  the  fiction  of 
per  quod  servitium  amisit  was  used  to  supplement  the  defective 
character  of  the  remedies  given  for  wrongs  to  domestic  relations, 
is  the  strongest  instance  of  the  evolution  of  an  unreasonable  set  of 
rules.6  The  manner  in  which  the  rights  of  the  parties  were  made 
dependent  upon  the  correct  appreciation  by  the  pleader  of  the 

1  Above  219-221.  -  Above  384,  392-397. 

8  (1621)  Cro.  Jac.  567  ;  above  423. 

*  (1707)  n  East  574  note  ;  above  426. 

s  (1853)  2  E.  and  B.  216 ;  above  429.  8  Above  42S-429. 


432  CRIME  AND  TORT 

right  form  of  action x — more  especially,  in  later  law,  on  the  often 
fine  distinction  between  Trespass  and  Case ; 2  and  the  impos- 
sibility of  joining  two  causes  of  action  which  fell  under  different 
forms,3 — are  both  striking  illustrations  of  the  technical  character  of 
its  rules.4 

But  secondly,  the  growth  of  specific  torts,  and  the  definition  of 
the  essential  characteristics  of  these  torts,  helped  to  concentrate 
attention  on  the  substantive  rules  of  the  law  of  tort.  In  the 
mediaeval  period  the  law  of  tort  was  largely  contained  in  the  rules 
as  to  the  competence  of  various  forms  of  action — Detinue  and 
various  forms  of  Trespass,  Case  and  the  various  forms  of  Case. 
During  this  period,  the  law  was  acquiring  a  number  of  substantive 
rules,  which  are  independent  of  adjective  law  ;  and  this  new 
importance  of  the  rules  of  substantive  law  will  increase  during  the 
eighteenth  and  early  nineteenth  centuries.  This  meant  that  the 
problem  of  distinguishing  damna  cum  from  damna  sine  injuria 
was  presented  to  the  courts  in  a  somewhat  different  form.  We 
have  seen  that,  in  the  Middle  Ages,  the  growth  of  the  action  on 
the  case  had  brought  this  problem  before  the  courts ; 5  and  in  the 
law  of  this  period  and  later  it  was  often  before  the  courts.  But, 
while  in  the  Middle  Ages  it  was  regarded  rather  as  a  problem  re- 
lating to  the  competence  of  actions,  in  later  law  it  is  regarded  as 
a  problem  relating  to  the  substantive  rights  of  the  parties.  It 
may  be  that,  in  many  cases,  "  discussions  of  legislative  principle 
have  been  darkened  by  arguments  on  the  limits  between  trespass 
and  case,  or  on  the  scope  of  a  general  issue  " ;  and  that  "  in  place 
of  a  theory  of  tort  we  have  a  theory  of  trespass."  6  For  all  that, 
it  is  true  that,  during  this  period,  the  law  is  much  nearer  to  a 
theory  of  tort  than  it  was  in  the  Middle  Ages. 

Thirdly,  these  developments  necessitated  a  thorough  revision 
of  the  mediaeval  principles  of  civil  liability  for  wrong.  We  have 
seen  that  many  of  the  later  developments  of  the  older  torts,  such 
as  assault  and  battery,  involved  a  consideration  of  the  intention  of 
the  defendant ; 7  an  intention  to  deceive  was  the  essence  of  deceit ; 
and    malice  was   an  essential  element    in    the   tort  of  malicious 

1  Maitland,  Forms  of  Action  298,  361-362. 

2  "  We  must  keep  up  the  boundaries  of  actions,  otherwise  we  shall  introduce  the 
utmost  confusion,"  Reynolds  v.  Clarke  (1726)  1  Str.  at  p.  635  per  Lord  Raymond,  C.J. ; 
this  dictum  was  cited  with  approval  by  Blackstone,  J.,  in  Scott  v.  Shepherd  (1773) 
2  W.  Bl.  at  p.  8g7  ;  see  also  Savignac  v.  Roome  (1794)  6  T.R.  at  p.  130  per  Grose,  J. 

3  "  A  man  who  had  been  assaulted  and  accused  of  theft  in  the  market  place  of  his 
town  was  obliged,  if  he  wished  for  redress  for  the  double  wrong,  to  issue  two  writs 
and  to  begin  two  litigations,  which  wound  their  course  through  distinct  pleadings  to 
two  separate  trials,"  Bowen,  Administration  of  Justice  in  the  Victorian  Period,  Essavs 
A.A.L.H.  i  518. 

4  For  other  illustrations  in  other  branches  of  the  law  see  vol.  i  634  and  n.  2,  645. 

6  Vol.  iii  408.  6  Holmes,  The  Common  Law  78. 

7  Above  422. 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  433 

prosecution.1  The  large  mass  of  wrongs  to  person  and  property 
remedied  by  actions  on  the  case,  were  coming  to  depend  on  the 
question  whether  the  defendant  had  acted  negligently  to  the 
damage  of  the  plaintiff,  and  not  merely  on  the  question  whether 
he  had  caused  him  damage  by  his  act  Commercial  necessities 
were  showing  that  the  mediaeval  rules  as  to  the  master's  liability 
for  the  acts  of  his  servants  were  too  narrow.  Of  the  manner  in 
which  all  these  causes  transformed  the  mediaeval  principles  of 
civil  liability  I  shall  speak  in  the  following  section. 

§  6.  The  Principles  of  Liability 

Criminal  Liability 

We  have  seen  that  during  the  mediaeval  period  criminal,  un- 
like civil  liability,  was  based  upon  the  presence  of  a  mens  rea. 
We  have  seen,  too,  that  the  rules  as  to  the  possible  defences  to 
a  criminal  charge,  and  as  to  incapacities  which  would  excuse 
from  guilt,  or  mitigate  punishment,  were  growing  more  precise ; 
and  that  this  growing  precision  was  partly  the  cause,  and  partly 
the  effect  of  the  firmness  with  which  the  central  principle  of  the 
criminal  liability — the  need  for  a  mens  rea — had  come  to  be 
grasped.2  During  this  period,  (i)  the  nature  of  this  mens  rea 
in  relation  to  various  specific  crimes  was  being  analysed  and 
elaborated ;  and  (2)  the  same  process  of  analysis  and  elaboration 
was  taking  place  with  reference,  both  to  the  incapacities  which 
would  excuse  from  guilt,  and  to  some  of  the  defences  which 
might  be  made  to  a  charge  of  crime.  Under  these  two  heads, 
therefore,  I  shall  sketch  shortly  the  development  of  this  branch 
of  the  law. 

(1)  The  requirement  of  mens  rea. 

It  was  well  settled  in  the  sixteenth  century  (in  spite  of  the 
opinion  to  the  contrary  held  in  the  fourteenth  century)3  that  a 
mere  intention  to  commit  a  crime,  unaccompanied  by  any  overt 
act,  entailed  no  criminal  liability.  "  The  imagination  of  the  mind 
to  do  wrong,"  it  was  said  in  Hales  v.  Petit,*  "  without  an  act  done,  is 
not  punishable  in  our  law,  neither  is  the  resolution  to  do  that  wrong 
which  he  does  not,  punishable,  but  the  doing  of  the  act  is  the  only 
point  which  the  law  regards ;  for  until  the  act  is  done  it  cannot 
be  an  offence  to  the  world,  and  when  the  act  is  done  it  is  punish- 
able." And  by  an  act  was  meant  a  voluntary  act,  so  that,  "  if  A 
by  force  takes  the  arm  of  B,  and  the  weapon  in  his  hand,  and 

1  Above  391.  *  Vol.  Hi  372-375. 

5  Ibid  373  and  n.  4.  4  (1563)  Plowdcn  at  p.  259. 

VOL.   VIII.— 28 


434  CRIME  AND  TORT 

therewith  stabs  C,  this  is  murder  in  A,  but  B  is  not  guilty."1  In 
fact,  the  manner  in  which  the  common  law  courts  adopted  the 
Star  Chamber's  view  as  to  the  criminality  of  attempts  to  commit 
crimes,2  and  treated  these  attempts  as  common  law  misdemeanours,3 
removed  the  chief  reason  for  reviving  the  dangerous  doctrine  that 
a  mere  intent  to  commit  a  crime  entailed  liability. 

To  produce  criminal  liability,  therefore,  there  must  be  both 
an  act  and  a  guilty  intent.  It  followed  that  if  one  killed  another 
accidentally  he  did  not  commit  murder — "  for  it  is  the  will  and 
intention  that  is  regularly  required,  as  well  as  the  act  and  event, 
to  make  the  offence  capital."4  So  in  the  case  of  larceny,  "as  it 
is  cepit  and  asportavit,  so  it  must  befelonice  or  animofurandi,  other- 
wise it  is  not  felony,  for  it  is  the  mind  that  makes  the  taking  of 
another's  goods  to  be  a  felony  or  a  bare  trespass  only."  5  It 
followed  also  that,  though  ignorance  of  law  never  excused  from 
criminal  liability,6  ignorance  of  fact  might,  if  it  negatived  any  sort 
of  guilty  intent7  This  principle  was  applied  in  1639,  in  the  case  of 
R.  v.  Levett*  where  the  accused,  under  the  mistaken  but  justifiable 
impression  that  a  person  in  the  house  was  a  burglar,  killed  her. 

The  more  difficult  question  now  arises,  what  is  the  nature  of 
this  guilty  intent  which  the  law  requires  as  a  condition  of  criminal 
liability  ?  The  answer  in  general  terms  is  that  it  is  different  in 
different  classes  of  crimes — in  1503,  for  instance,  Marowe  saw 
that  the  guilty  intent  required  for  murder  was  different  from  that 
required  for  larceny ; 9  and  that,  in  certain  classes  of  crimes,  the 
law  has  specified  certain  kinds  of  acts,  and  ruled  that  the  doing  of 
them  amounts  to  the  guilty  intent  required  by  the  law  for  the 
commission  of  these  crimes.  We  have  seen  that  in  other  branches 
of  the  law  there  was  a  tendency  in  this  direction,  which  was  partly 
due  to  the  difficulty  of  proving  intent,  where  the  parties  to  an 
action  were  not  competent  witnesses  ; 10  and  no  doubt  the  tendency 
was  emphasized  in  the  criminal  law  from  motives  of  public 
policy.  The  safety  of  the  state  and  its  citizens  made  it  necessary 
that  the  meagre  mediaeval  rules  should  be  extended.     The  result 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  434,  citing  Reniger  v.  Fogossa  (1551),  Plowden  at  p.  19  ;  but  it  was 
only  physical  violence  which  operated  in  this  way — "  if  it  be  only  a  moral  force,  as  by 
threatening,  duress,  or  imprisonment  etc.  this  excuseth  not,"  ibid ;  see  below  443-445. 

2  Vol.  v  201.  3  Kenny,  Criminal  Law  82. 

4  Hale,  P.C.  i  38.  5  Ibid  508.  6  Ibid  42. 

7,4  But  in  some  cases  ignorantia  facti  doth  excuse,  for  such  an  ignorance  many 
times  makes  the  act  itself  morally  involuntary,"  ibid. 
»  (1639)  Cro.  Car.  538. 

9  De  Pace,  Oxford  Studies  in  Social  and  Legal  History,  vol.  vii  378. — "  Et  nota 
que  en  mort  de  home  lentent  de  celui  que  fait  le  morte  ne  fait  le  felony  come  il  fait 
de  Theft.  .  .  quar  si  home  entende  de  bater  ascun  person  et  en  cette  baterie  il  tua  une 
autre,  ceo  est  felony  nient  obstante  son  entent  ne  fut  de  luy  occider.  Mes  en  ascun 
cas  de  mort  de  homme  entent  ferra  le  felony." 

10  Vol.  iv  481-482. 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  485 

is  that  the  mens  rea  or  guilty  intent  required  by  the  law,  though 
it  originated  in  the  idea  that  accompanying  the  act  there  must  be 
an  element  of  moral  blameworthiness,  though  it  still  connotes  such 
moral  blameworthiness,  has  become  a  very  technical  notion.  Its 
assumption  of  this  technical  form  is  mainly  the  work  of  this  period 
of  our  legal  history.  Let  us  take  as  illustrations  of  this  process 
the  manner  in  which  it  has  come  to  be  defined  in  relation  to 
murder,  manslaughter,  and  larceny. 

It  is  clear  that  Coke  was  stating  a  well  settled  principle  when 
he  says  of  the  "  malice  prepensed  "  or  "  malice  aforethought "  which 
is  necessary  for  murder,  that  it  exists  "when  one  compasseth  to 
kill  wound  or  beat  another  and  doth  it  sedato  animo  "  ;  and  that 
this  malice  was  "  so  odious  in  law,"  that  "  though  it  be  intended 
against  one,  it  shall  be  extended  towards  another." l  So  far  as  the 
compassing  is  a  compassing  to  kill,  this  definition  gives  us  the  natural 
meaning  of  the  term ;  but  in  the  statement  that  a  compassing  to 
wound  or  beat,  and  still  more  in  the  statement  that  a  blow  intended 
for  another,  will,  if  death  ensues,  amount  to  malice  aforethought,  we 
are  departing  from  the  natural  meaning  of  words.  But  this  exten- 
sion was  still  further  extended  in  the  course  of  the  sixteenth  century. 
It  was  held  by  a  majority  of  the  judges  in  1 536,2  that,  if  a  person 
was  killed  accidentally  by  one  of  the  members  of  a  band  engaged 
on  a  felonious  act,  all  could  be  held  to  be  guilty  of  murder.  The 
judges  in  this  case  were  not  unanimous ; 3  but  it  was  the  opinion  of 
the  majority  which  has  prevailed.4  A  fortiori  malice  was  implied 
if  A  assaults  B  with  intent  to  rob  him,  and  in  the  course  of  the 
struggle  A  kills  B.5  "  He  that  doth  a  cruel  act  voluntarily,"  said 
Holt,  C. J.,  "  does  it  of  malice  prepensed." 6  This  idea  was  further 
extended  to  cover  the  case  where  an  act  likely  to  cause  damage 
had  caused  death,  though  there  was  no  intention  to  hurt  anyone.7 
It  was  not  difficult  to  conclude  from  this  that  murder  was  com- 
mitted, if  death  had  ensued  as  the  result  of  doing  any  unlawful 

1  Third  Instit.  51,  citing  inter  aba  Bracton's  dictum  at  f.  155a  that  "  si  quis  unum 
percusserit  et  occiderit,  cum  alium  percutere  vellet  in  felonia,  tenetur  "  ;  this  was  no 
doubt  the  source  of  Marowe's  similar  statement,  above  434  n.  9.  Halloway's  Case 
(1629)  Cro.  Car.  131 ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  466  ;  we  have  seen  that  Marowe  states  the  law  even 
more  widely. 

2  Mansell  and  Herbert's  Case,  Dyer  128b — a  mob  had  assembled  in  order  to 
assault  and  rob  a  house,  and  a  woman  coming  out  of  the  house  was  killed  by  a  stone 
thrown  by  one  of  the  mob  at  another  person. 

3  The  dissentient  judges  were  evidently  reluctant  to  extend  the  meaning  of  malice ; 
they  said,  "  no  malice  was  intended  against  the  woman,  and  murder  cannot  be  ex- 
tended beyond  what  was  intended." 

4  Above  329  ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  441-442. 
8  Ibid  465  ;  Coke,  Third  Instit  52. 

8  R.  v.  Mawgridge  (1707)  Kelying  at  p.  127  ;  cf.  Coke,  Third  Inst.,  62—"  if  it 
be  voluntary  the  law  implieth  malice." 

7  See  R.  v.  Hull  (1664)  Kelying,  40  ;  Foster  Crown  Law,  262-263  ;  Kenny  op.  cit. 
135-136. 


436  CRIME  AND  TORT 

act.1  This  wide  rule  was,  however,  narrowed  down  by  Foster  to 
the  case  when  the  unlawful  act  was  also  felonious  and  malum  in 
se — e.g.  if  A,  intending  to  steal  B's  poultry,  shoots  at  them  and 
accidentally  kills  C.2  But  it  is  probable  that  even  this  mitigated 
form  of  the  rule  would  not  now  be  followed.3  Another  extension 
recognized  in  this  period  is,  however,  still  part  of  the  law — the 
case  where  a  person  kills  an  officer  of  the  law,  or  magistrate,  in 
the  regular 4  execution  of  his  duty,  though  he  had  no  intention  of 
killing  him.5  In  these  ways,  through  the  decisions  given  in  this 
period,  the  particular  mens  rea  known  as  malice  aforethought 
which  was  needed  to  make  homicide  murder,  was  so  extended 
that  it  has  come  to  be,  as  Professor  Kenny  has  said,  merely  an 
"arbitrary  symbol."  G  "  For  the  malice  may  have  in  it  nothing  really 
malicious,  and  need  never  be  really  aforethought."  7 

Manslaughter  is  said  by  Hale  to  be  "  the  voluntary  killing  of 
another  without  malice  express  or  implied."  8  But  this  does  not 
mean,  as  Professor  Kenny  points  out,9  that  there  is  no  mens  rea. 
It  merely  means  that  the  guilty  intention  is  of  a  different  character. 
The  character  of  the  guilty  intent  required  was,  it  would  seem  from 
Hale,  elucidated  chiefly  by  cases  which  drew  the  line  between 
murder  on  the  one  hand,  and  a  merely  accidental  killing  on  the 
other.  Some  of  these  cases  depend  on  the  fact  that  the  person 
who  caused  the  death  has  been  careless — e.g.  the  case  of  the  builder 
who  drops  a  piece  of  stone  without  due  warning ; 10  and  often  the 
question  whether  murder  or  manslaughter  has  been  committed  will 
depend  on  the  degree  of  carelessness  shown.11  Others  depend  on 
the  fact  that,  though  there  was  no  intention  to  cause  death,  the 
death  was  in  fact  caused  by  the  accused  in  the  course  of  doing  an 

1  "  If  the  act  be  unlawful  it  is  murder.  As  if  A  meaning  to  steal  a  deer  in  the 
park  of  B  shooteth  at  the  deer,  and  by  the  glance  of  the  arrow  killeth  a  boy  that  is 
hidden  in  a  bush :  this  is  murder,  for  that  the  act  was  unlawful,  although  A  had  no 
intent  to  hurt  the  boy  nor  knew  not  of  him,''  Coke,  Third  Instit.  56. 

2  Crown  Law,  258-259 — "  The  rule  I  have  laid  down  supposeth  that  the  act  from 
which  death  ensued  was  malum  in  se.  For  if  it  was  barely  malum  prohibitum,  as 
shooting  at  game  by  a  person  not  qualified  by  statute  law  to  keep  or  use  a  gun  for 
that  purpose,  the  case  of  a  person  so  offending  will  fall  under  the  same  rule  as  that  of 
a  qualified  man." 

3  Kenny,  op.  cit.  137-138. 

4  Cook's  Case  (1639)  Cro.  Car.  537  ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  458. 

5  Young's  Case  (1586)  4  Co.  Rep.  40a ;  Mackalley's  Case  (1612)  9  Co.  Rep.  at 
ff.  68a,  68b  ;  Hale,  P.C.  i  457  seqq.  G  Op.  cit.  132 

7  Ibid  132-133  as  Stephen,  J.,  said  in  R.  v.  SernS  (1887)  16  Cox  C.C.  at  p.  312, 
"  the  words  malice  aforethought  are  technical.  You  must  not,  therefore,  construe 
them  or  suppose  that  they  can  be  construed  by  ordinary  rules  of  language.  The  words 
have  to  be  construed  according  to  a  long  series  of  decided  cases,  which  have  given 
them  meanings  different  from  those  which  might  be  supposed." 

8  P.C.  i  466. 

9  Op.  cit.  115 — "  we  shall  better  avoid  confusion  of  language  if  we  say,  *  without 
any  of  those  more  guilty  forms  of  malice  which  amount  to  murderous  malice.'  For 
malice,  in  its  wide  legal  sense  (that  is  to  say  mens  rea)  is  essential  to  every  crime." 

M  R.  v.  Hull  (1664)  Kelyng  40.  "  Above  435  n.  7. 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  437 

unlawful  act — eg.  playing  at  an  unlawful  game1 — but  an  act  not 
sufficiently  unlawful  to  make  the  homicide  murder.2  Others  de- 
pend on  the  fact  that  the  death  occurred  in  the  course  of  a  sudden 
quarrel  which  negatived  the  idea  of  premeditation ; 3  and,  for  the 
same  reason,  a  homicide  committed  under  severe  provocation  will 
generally  be  manslaughter,  if  done  in  the  heat  of  the  moment4 
Here  again,  therefore,  the  mens  rea  required  by  the  law  may  be  of 
the  most  various  kinds,  and  of  all  degrees  of  moral  guilt  It  is  for 
this  reason  that  manslaughter  is  said  to  be  "an  elastic  crime,"  " for 
the  degrees  of  guilt  which  may  accompany  it  extend  from  the  verge 
of  murder  to  the  verge  of  excusable  homicide." 5 

In  the  case  of  larceny  it  is  the  intention  to  steal  which  makes 
all  the  difference  between  the  felony  and  a  bare  trespass.  But 
whether  this  intention  is  present  or  not  must  be  judged  by  the 
circumstances  of  the  case.  Hale  considered  that  it  was  possible  to 
illustrate,  but  not  to  define,  "  all  the  circumstances  evidencing  a 
felonious  intent"  6  From  that  day  to  this,  the  reported  cases  have 
gone  on  illustrating  these  circumstances,  till  it  is  possible  to  lay 
down  one  or  two  general  rules ;  and,  even  when  Hale  wrote,  one 
or  two  of  them  had  emerged.  Thus,  it  was  no  felony  to  take  A's 
horse  from  a  common  for  a  ride,  when  the  horse  was  restored  to 
the  common  at  the  end  of  the  ride."  Similarly,  if  my  servant 
takes  my  horse  and  uses  him  for  his  own  occasions,  it  is  no  felony 
if  he  returns  him  ;  but  if,  while  on  his  journey,  he  sells  him  as  if 
he  were  his  own,  "that  act  of  selling"  is  declarative  of  his  first 
taking  to  be  felonious."  8  Again,  "  if  A,  thinking  he  hath  a  title 
to  the  horse  of  B,  seiseth  as  his  own,  or,  supposing  that  B  holds  of 
him,  distrains  the  horse  of  B  without  cause,  this  regularly  makes 
it  no  felony  but  a  trespass,  because  there  is  a  pretence  of  title,  but 
yet  this  may  be  but  a  trick  to  colour  a  felony,  and  the  ordinary 
discovery  of  a  felonious  intent  is,  if  the  party  doth  it  secretly,  or 
being  charged  with  the  goods  denies  it "  9 

These  illustrations  show  that  the  growth  of  the  criminal  law  is 
largely  bound  up  with  the  elaboration  and  differentiation  of  the 
different  sorts  of  mental  attitude,  which  is  needed  to  constitute  a 
mens  rea  in  different  classes  of  crimes ;  for,  when  this  elaboration 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  472-473. 

-  See  Kenny,  op.  cit.  no ;  it  is  on  this  principle  that  one  who  kills  another  in  a 
duel  is  guilty  of  murder,  vol.  v  199-201. 
3  Coke,  Third  Instit.  55  ;  above  303. 

*  Coke,  Third  Instit,  55  ;  Royley's  Case  (1612)  Cro.  Jac.  296  ;  Maddy's  Case  (1671) 
1  Vent.  158. 

5  Kenny,  op.  cit.  124. 

•  '*  But  in  cases  of  larceny  the  variety  of  circumstances  is  so  great,  and  the  com- 
plications thereof  so  mingled,  that  it  is  impossible  to  prescribe  all  the  circumstances 
evidencing  a  felonious  intent,  or  the  contrary,  but  the  same  must  be  left  to  the  due  and 
attentive  consideration  of  the  judge  and  jury,"  P.C.  i  509. 

7  Ibid.  "Ibid.  Mbid. 


438  CRIME  AND  TORT 

and  differentiation  have  been  made,  we  have  gone  a  long  way  to 
defining  the  most  essential  features  of  these  different  crimes.  We 
shall  now  see  that  this  same  process  has  helped  the  law  to  attain 
some  more  definite  rules  as  to  the  various  incapacities  which  will 
excuse  from  guilt,  and  has  had  some  influence  on  the  law  as  to 
some  of  the  defences  which  can  be  made  to  a  charge  of  crime. 

(2)  Incapacities  and  defences. 

The  three  incapacities  of  which  I  intend  to  speak  shortly  are 
infancy,  insanity,  and  drunkenness. 

Infancy.  It  would  seem  that  the  modern  rules  relating  to  the 
incapacity  of  infants  were  first  settled  in  the  case  of  capital  offences 
— treason  and  the  felonies.  We  have  seen  that  it  was  well  settled 
in  this  period  that  a  child  below  the  age  of  seven  could  not  be 
guilty  of  a  felony,  that  between  seven  and  fourteen  there  was  a 
rebuttable  presumption  to  the  same  effect,  and  that  over  fourteen 
his  capacity  was  regarded  as  normal.1  In  fact,  from  that  time  to 
this,  there  have  been  a  few  instances  in  which  children  of  under 
fourteen  have  been  convicted,  and  one  or  two  in  which  they  have 
even  been  executed ; 2  and  Hale  testifies  to  the  fact  that  so  many 
crimes  were  committed  by  youths  between  fourteen  and  twenty- 
one,  that,  "  if  they  should  have  impunity  by  privilege  of  such  their 
minority,  no  man's  life  or  estate  could  be  safe."3  With  regard  to 
crimes  under  the  degree  of  felony,  the  law  was  not  by  any  means 
so  certain.  In  the  case  of  crimes  of  violence,  such  as  riot  or 
battery,  the  same  rule  as  that  applicable  to  felony  was  enforced  in 
Hale's  time.4  But  then,  as  now,  the  misdemeanours  covered  a 
wide  field,  and  some  of  them,  then  as  now,  were  remote  from  the 
sphere  of  crime.  For  this  reason,  in  certain  of  these  cases,  the 
law  adopted  the  rule  applicable  to  the  proprietary  or  contractual 
capacity  of  infants,  and  exempted  them  from  liability  if  they 
were  under  twenty-one.  Thus  for  mere  nonfeasance  (unless  the 
liability  were  ratione  tenurae)  they  were  exempt,  because  laches 
could  not  be  imputed  to  them.5  Similarly,  if  the  law  imposed  a 
penalty  for  a  wrongful  dealing  with  property,  but  the  penalty  could 
be  regarded  as  only  collateral  to  the  main  purpose  of  the  law,  viz. 
to  discourage  such  dealings  with  property,  an  infant  under  twenty- 
one  escaped.*'     But  these  exemptions  are  now  probably  obsolete  ; 

1  Vol.  iii  372. 

2  Hale,  P.C.  i  26-27  ;  Bl.  Comm.  iv  23-24  ;  Kenny,  op.  cit.  50-51. 

3 "Experience  makes  us  know,  that  every  day  murders,  bloodshed,  burglaries, 
larcenies,  burning  of  houses,  rapes,  clipping  and  counterfeiting  of  money,  are  com- 
mitted by  youths  above  fourteen  and  under  twenty-one  ;  and  if  they  should  have  im- 
punity by  the  privilege  of  such  their  minority  no  man's  life  or  estate  could  be  safe," 
P.C.  i  25. 

4  Ibid  20.  5  Ibid  ;  see  R.  v.  Sutton  (1835)  3  Ad.  and  E.  at  pp.  601-603. 

fi  "  When  the  corporal  punishment  is  but  collateral,  and  not  the  direct  intention  of 
the  proceeding  against  the  infant  for  his  misdemeanour,  there  in  many  cases  the  infant 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  439 

and  for  all  ordinary  misdemeanours  the  rule  is  the  same  as  in  the 
case  of  felony. 

Insanity. — "  No  felony  or  murder,"  says  Coke,1  "can  be  com- 
mitted without  a  felonious  intent  and  purpose  .  .  . ;  but  furiosus 
non  intelligit  quid  agit,  et  animo  et  ratione  caret,  et  non  multum 
distat  a  brutis,  as  Bracton  saith,  and  therefore  he  cannot  have  a 
felonious  intent"  For  this  reason  insanity  was  a  bar  either  to 
the  institution  or  the  continuance  of  criminal  proceedings.  We 
have  seen  that  it  was  settled  in  the  mediaeval  period  that  madness, 
if  it  existed  when  the  crime  was  committed,  negatived  liability.2 
It  was  further  settled  in  this  period  that,  if  a  person  of  sound 
mind  commits  a  crime  and  becomes  mad  before  his  arraignment, 
he  cannot  be  arraigned ;  "  and  if  such  person  after  his  plea  and 
before  his  trial,  become  of  non-sane  memory,  he  shall  not  be  tried  ; 
or,  if  after  trial  he  become  of  non-sane  memory,  he  shall  not 
receive  judgment ;  or,  if  after  judgment  he  become  of  non-sane 
memory,  his  execution  shall  be  spared ;  for  were  he  of  sound 
memory,  he  might  allege  somewhat  in  stay  of  judgment  or 
execution."3  In  spite  of  some  doubts  as  to  whether  these  rules 
were  applicable  to  high  treason,  if  it  took  the  form  of  an  attempt 
to  kill  the  king,4  these  rules  were  recognized  to  be  of  universal 
application  in  the  seventeenth  century. 

There  remain  the  much  more  difficult  questions,  (i)  what  the 
law  will  regard  as  such  insanity  as  will  totally  exempt  from 
criminal  liability;  and  (ii)  how  it  will  treat  what  may  be  called 
cases  of  partial  insanity,  that  is  cases  where  a  person  is  clearly 
not  sane,  and  yet  not  wholly  bereft  of  reason.  No  part  of  the 
criminal  law  is  so  fluid  as  this,  largely  because  it  is  a  question 
partly  belonging  to  legal  and  partly  to  medical  science ;  and 
because  the  latter  science  has,  as  medical  knowledge  advances 
or  the  fashion  in  medical  theory  changes,  adopted  very  variable 
views  on  this  matter.5  On  two  points  however  the  law  has  been 
clear  from  the  seventeenth  century  onwards.  Firstly,  it  is  not 
necessary,  in  order  to  escape  liability,  that  the  accused  should 

under  the  age  of  twenty-one  shall  be  spared,  though  possibly  the  punishment  be  enacted 
by  Parliament.  If  an  infant  of  the  age  of  eighteen  years  be  convict  of  a  disseisin  with 
force,  yet  he  shall  not  be  imprisoned.  .  .  .  If  an  infant  be  convict  in  an  action  of  tres- 
pass vi  et  armis,  the  entry  must  be  nihil  dc  fine,  led  pardonatur  quia  infans,"  P.C.  i 
21. 

1  Beverley's  Case  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep  at  f.  124b. 

2  Vol.  iii  372  and  n.  9.  3  Hale,  P.C.  i  35. 

*  Coke  said  in  Beverley's  Case  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  124b  that,  "  in  some  cases 
non  compos  mentis  may  commit  high  treason  as  if  he  kills  or  offers  to  kill  the  king  "  ; 
but  this  is  contrary  to  what  he  says  in  Third  Instit.  6  ;  and  that  it  is  not  law  is  shown 
by  33  Henry  VIII.  c.  20  (see  vol.  iv  409-500),  as  is  practically  admitted  by  Coke, 
loc.  cit.  and  by  Hale,  P.C.  i  35,  37 ;  but  Hale,  P.C.  i  37,  though  he  proves  it  to  be 
a  baseless  exception,  refused  to  deny  it  "  because  it  tends  so  much  to  the  safety  of 
the  king's  person." 

5  On  the  whole  subject  see  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  chap.  xix. 


440  CRIME  AND  TORT 

have  been  found  a  lunatic  by  inquisition.1  "  The  trial  of  the 
incapacity  of  a  party  indicted  or  appealed  of  a  capital  offence  is, 
upon  his  plea  of  not  guilty,  by  the  jury  upon  his  arraignment, 
who  are  to  inquire  thereupon  touching  such  incapacity  of  the 
prisoner,  and  whether  it  be  to  such  a  degree  as  may  excuse  him 
from  the  guilt  of  a  capital  offence."2  Secondly,  the  law  presumes 
every  one  to  be  sane  till  the  contrary  be  proved.3 

(i)  The  first  question — what  the  law  will  regard  as  such  total 
insanity  as  will  exempt  from  all  liability — is,  as  Hale  says,  a 
question  of  fact.  But  on  the  question  how  this  question  of  fact 
shall  be  answered  the  law  has  given  very  different  answers 
at  different  periods.  Professor  Kenny  says,4  "At  one  time  a 
view  prevailed  that  no  lunatic  ought  to  escape  punishment  unless 
he  were  so  totally  deprived  of  understanding  and  memory  as  to 
be  as  ignorant  of  what  he  was  doing  as  a  wild  beast.  But,  ever 
since  the  epoch-making  speech  of  Erskine  in  defence  of  Hadfield 
(in  the  year  1800),5  a  view  at  once  more  rational  and  humane  has 
prevailed,  which  bases  the  test  upon  the  presence  or  absence  of 
the  faculty  of  distinguishing  right  from  wrong."  Later,  a  still 
more  precise  test  was  evolved.  Did  the  accused  know  the  nature 
of  the  act  which  he  was  doing,  and,  if  he  did  know  it,  did  he 
know  it  was  wrong?  If  so,  and  if  the  act  was  contrary  to  law,  he 
is  punishable.6  This  test  was  suggested  in  reference  to  persons 
suffering  from  insane  delusions,  i.e.  the  partially  insane;  but  it 
obviously  supplies  a  test  for  coming  to  a  conclusion  whether  or 
not  any  person  is  wholly  insane. 

(ii)  The  second  question — the  treatment  to  be  accorded  to 
cases  of  partial  insanity — is  far  more  difficult.  Hale  is  evidently 
at  a  loss  how  to  deal  with  these  cases.  In  cases  of  recurrent 
intervals  of  madness,  indeed,  there  is  no  difficulty.  If  during 
these  intervals  the  person  affected  is  wholly  mad,  the  rule  as  to 

1  As  to  this  see  vol.  i.  474-475.  2  Hale,  P.C.  i  33.  3  Ibid. 

4  Op.  cit.  53,  citing  R.  v.  Arnold  (1724)  16  S.T.  at  p.  765,  where  Tracey,  J.,  said, 
"  it  must  be  a  man  that  is  totally  deprived  of  his  understanding  and  memory,  and  doth 
not  know  what  he  is  doing,  no  more  than  an  infant,  than  a  brute,  or  wild  beast ; 
therefore  I  must  leave  it  to  your  consideration,  whether  the  condition  this  man  was  in, 
as  it  is  represented  to  you  on  one  side,  or  the  other,  doth  show  a  man  who  knew  what 
he  was  doing,  and  was  able  to  distinguish  whether  he  was  doing  good  or  evil,  and 
understood  what  he  did." 

5  27  S.T.  1282  ;  Stephen  H.C.L.  ii  159. 

6  M'Naghten's  Case  (1847)  10  CI.  and  Fin.  at  p.  210 ;  as  is  there  said,  "  the  mode 
of  putting  the  latter  part  of  the  question  to  the  jury  on  these  occasions  has  generally 
been,  whether  the  accused  at  the  time  of  doing  the  act  knew  the  difference  between 
right  and  wrong  :  which  mode,  though  rarely,  if  ever,  leading  to  any  mistake  with  the 
jury,  is  not,  as  we  conceive,  so  accurate  when  put  generally  and  in  the  abstract,  as 
when  put  with  reference  to  the  party's  knowledge  of  right  and  wrong  in  respect  to  the 
very  act  with  which  he  is  charged  "  ;  as  can  be  seen  from  the  way  in  which  Tracey,  J., 
used  this  test  in  R.  v.  Arnold,  above  n.  4,  the  new  test  set  out  by  the  judges  in 
M'Naghten's  case  is  more  favourable  to  the  accused,  and  better  calculated  to  give 
effect  to  the  modern  ideas  as  to  the  treatment  to  be  accorded  to  the  insane. 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  441 

total  insanity  applies.1  But  if  the  accused  is  not  wholly  destitute 
of  reason,  he  inclines  to  the  view  that  such  insanity  will  not 
excuse  in  the  case  of  any  capital  crime — "for  doubtless,  most 
persons,  that  are  felons  of  themselves,  are  under  a  degree  of  partial 
insanity,  when  they  commit  these  offences."  On  the  whole,  he 
can  only  recommend  that  each  case  should  be  treated  on  its  own 
merits,  and  concludes  with  the  somewhat  fatuous  suggestion  that, 
as  such  persons  have  generally  as  great  understanding  as  a  child  of 
fourteen,  they  should  be  treated  accordingly.2  But,  in  spite  of 
this,  Hale's  treatment  of  the  subject  is,  as  Stephen  says,  "  marked 
by  his  ordinary  shrewdness  and  judgment,  and  does  recognize, 
though  faintly  and  imperfectly,  the  main  divisions  of  the  subject";3 
and  Blackstone4  could  add  little  to  his  statement. 

No  authoritative  pronouncement  on  this  subject  was  made  till 
1843  ;  and  then  the  test  suggested  was,  as  we  have  seen,  whether 
the  accused  knew  the  nature  of  the  act  he  was  doing,  and  whether 
he  knew  that  it  was  wrong.  It  followed  from  this  that,  if  a  person 
was  labouring  under  a  partial  delusion,  and  was  not  in  other 
respects  insane,  "  he  must  be  considered  in  the  same  situation  as 
to  responsibility  as  if  the  facts  with  respect  to  which  the  delusions 
exist  were  real."  5  Since  1843,  however,  the  law  has  developed, 
because  the  discoveries  of  medical  science  have  revealed  more  of 
the  infinite  complexities  of  the  problem  of  insanity.  Thus  it  is  now 
recognized  that,  to  the  mind  of  a  madman,  there  may  be  a  con- 
nection between  his  delusion  and  his  crime,  which  is  not  apparent 
to  a  sane  person ;  and  that  account  should  be  taken  of  the  effect 
of  insanity  upon  emotion  and  will  power.6  These  considerations 
have  led  to  a  more  merciful  administration  of  the  law,  than  a 
literal  following  of  the  rules  laid  down  in  1843,  would  justify.  It 
is  obvious  that  the  development  of  this  branch  of  the  law  must,  to 
some  extent,  depend  upon  the  development  of  medical  science. 

Drunkenness. — The  rule  laid  down  in  the  sixteenth  century 
was  short  and  clear — drunkenness  was  no  excuse  for  crime,  but 
rather  an  aggravation  of  the  offence.  "  If  a  person  that  is  drunk," 
it  was  said  in  1 5 5 1,7  "kills  another,  this  shall  be  felony,  and 
he  shall  be  hanged  for  it,  and  yet  he  did  it  through  ignorance, 
for  when  he  was  drunk  he  had  no  understanding  nor  memory  ; 
but  in  as  much  as  that  ignorance  was  occasioned  by  his  own  act 
and  folly,  and  he  might  have  avoided  it,  he  shall  not  be  privileged 
thereby " ;  and  Coke,8  Hawkins 9  and  Blackstone  10  lay  down  the 
law  in  the  same  way.     Hale,  however,  allows  two  modifications  of 

1  Hale,  P.C.  i  30-31.  2  Ibid  30. 

3  H.C.L.  ii  150-151.  4Comm.  iv  24-25. 

5M'Naghten's  Case  (1843)  10  CI.  and  Fin.  at  pp.  209-211. 

6  Kenny,  op.  cit.  55-56.  7  Reniger  v.  Fogossa,  Plowden  at  p.  19. 

8  Beverley's  Case  (1603)  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  125a  ;  Co.  Litt.  247a. 

9  P.C.  Bk.  1  cap.  1  §  6.  10  Cornm.  iv  25-26, 


442  CRIME  AND  TORT 

this  rule.  Firstly,  if  the  intoxication  was  not  caused  by  his  own 
fault,  as  where  it  was  caused  by  "  the  unskilfulness  of  his  physician 
or  by  the  contrivance  of  his  enemies  "  ;  and,  secondly,  if  by  habitual 
drunkenness  "an  habitual  or  fixed  phrensy  be  caused."  l  In  the 
first  case  it  would  seem  that,  if  the  effect  of  the  intoxication  was 
such  that  a  temporary  or  a  permanent  insanity  were  caused,  the 
person  so  affected  was  to  be  treated  as  if  he  were  insane.  But 
there  seem  to  be  no  cases  of  this  kind  in  the  books ;  and,  as  we 
shall  see  immediately,  the  development  of  the  law  as  to  the  effect 
of  drunkenness  on  criminal  liability  has  removed  the  necessity  for 
this  exception.  Probably  at  the  present  day  drunkenness,  whether 
caused  by  the  accused's  own  fault  or  not,  will  have  the  same  effect 
on  his  liability  for  a  crime  committed  while  in  that  state.  At 
most  the  fact  that  the  drunkenness  was  not  caused  by  his  own 
fault,  would,  if  did  not  excuse  from  liability,  be  a  ground  for  a 
mitigation  of  punishment.  In  the  second  case  the  accused  is,  as 
Hale  says,2  treated  as  insane.  But  at  the  present  day  this  treat- 
ment is  accorded,  both  in  the  case  where  the  insanity  is  "fixed  and 
habitual,"  and  where  it  is  merely  temporary.  "Drunkenness," 
said  Stephen,  J.,3  "  is  one  thing,  and  the  diseases  to  which 
drunkenness  leads  are  different  things;  and  if  a  man  by  drunken- 
ness brings  on  a  state  of  disease  which  causes  such  a  degree  of 
madness  even  for  a  time,  as  would  have  relieved  him  from  re- 
sponsibility, if  it  had  been  caused  in  any  other  way,  then  he  would 
not  be  criminally  responsible." 

It  is  in  respect  of  the  effect  of  drunkenness,  which  does  not 
fall  under  either  of  these  two  heads,  that  the  law  in  the  nineteenth 
century  has  departed  from  the  older  rule.4  If  drunkenness  does  not 
amount  to  insanity,  the  drunkard  can,  unlike  the  madman,5  be  tried 
and  convicted.6  But,  under  the  influence  probably  of  the  contem- 
porary modifications  which  were  taking  place  in  the  law  as  to 
insanity,7  the  judges  began  to  think  that  drunkenness  should  be 
allowed  to  modify  or  negative  criminal  liability  in  certain  cases. 
But  exactly  what  these  conditions  were,  and  how  in  principle  they 
should  operate,  was  for  some  time  not  very  clear.  There  are  some 
loose  dicta  in  the  earlier  cases  ; 8  but  in  the  middle  and  the  latter 

1  P.C.  i  32.  2  ibid. 

3  R.  v.  Davis  (1881)  14  Cox  C.C.  at  p.  564. 

4  "  The  law  stood  as  thus  expressed  for  many  years,  and,  as  far  as  we  know,  the 
point  was  first  decided  in  a  contrary  sense  in  R.  v.  Grindley  decided  in  the  year  1S19," 
R.  v.  Meade  [1909]  1  K.B.  at  p.  898. 

8  Above  439. 

6  See  Director  of  Public  Prosecutions  v.  Beard  [1920]  A.C.  479. 

7  Above  440-441. 

8  Thus  in  R.  v.  Grindley,  1  Russell,  Crimes  (7th  ed.)  i  88  n.  b,  Holroyd,  J.,  said 
that  the  fact  that  party  was  drunk,  was  a  material  fact  to  be  considered  in  coming  to  a 
conclusion  whether  or  not  an  act  was  premeditated  ;  but  this  was  repudiated  by  Park,  J., 
in  R.  v.  Carroll  (1835)  7  C.  and  P.  at  p.  147,  who  said  that  Holroyd,  J.,  had  retracted 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  443 

half  of  the  nineteenth  century,  it  was  coming  to  be  thought  that, 
"  where  intent  is  of  the  essence  of  a  crime  with  which  a  person  is 
charged,  that  intent  may  be  disproved  by  showing  that  at  the  time 
of  the  act  charged,  the  prisoner  was  in  a  state  of  drunkenness,  in 
which  state  he  was  incapable  of  forming  the  intent"  l  But  in 
1909,  in  R.  v.  Meade,  the  rule  was  laid  down  more  broadly.  It 
was  said  that  the  presumption  that  a  man  intends  the  natural 
consequences  of  his  acts,  may  be  rebutted  by  showing  that  his 
mind  was  "  so  affected  by  the  drink  he  had  taken,  that  he  was 
incapable  of  knowing  that  what  he  was  doing  was  dangerous,  i.e. 
likely  to  inflict  serious  injury."2  But  in  1920,  in  the  case  of  the 
Director  of  Public  Prosecutions  v.  Beard,3  the  House  of  Lords 
put  the  law  on  a  clear  and  logical  footing,  by  holding  that,  in  as 
much  as  a  mens  rea  of  one  sort  or  another  is,  with  very  few  ex- 
ceptions,4 a  necessary  constituent  of  all  crimes,  the  true  rule  is  that, 
if  the  drunkenness  has  produced  in  a  person  accused  of  a  crime,  an 
incapacity  to  form  the  particular  intent  necessary  for  the  commis- 
sion of  that  crime,  he  cannot  be  convicted  ; 5  and  that  it  is  only  in 
these  circumstances  that  drunkenness,  not  amounting  to  insanity,  is 
a  defence. 6 

Let  us  now  turn  to  certain  defences  which  rest  ultimately  on 
the  fact  that,  in  the  circumstances,  no  mens  rea  is  imputable. 
These  defences  are  coercion,  compulsion,  and  necessity. 

Coercion. — This,  as  Hale  points  out,"  is  not  usually  a  defence. 
The  doctrine  of  ministerial  responsibility  had,  when  Hale  wrote, 
been  well  established,  and  prevented  the  royal  command  from 
being  an  excuse  for  the  commission  of  crime. s  It  was  also  clear 
that  neither  the  command  of  a  parent  to  his  child,  nor  of  a  master 
to  his  servant,  was  any  defence.9  The  only  relationship  which 
could  give  rise  to  this  defence  was  that  of  husband  and  wife.  We 
have  seen  that,  during  the  mediaeval  period,  it  was  recognized 
that,  if  a  married  woman  committed  certain  crimes  under  the  coer- 
cion of  her  husband,  she  escaped  from  liability.10     This  rule  was 

his  opinion  ;  in  R.  v.  Monkhouse  (1849)  4  Cox  C.C.  at  p.  56  Coleridge,  J.,  ruled  that 
drunkenness  might  be  a  defence, "  if  such  as  to  prevent  his  restraining  himself  from  com- 
mitting the  act  in  question  "  ;  cp.  Director  of  Public  Prosecutions  v.  Beard  [1920]  A.C. 
at  p.  495. 

1  R.  v.  Meade  [1909]  1  K.B.  at  p.  898. 

3  At  p.  898.  *  [1920]  A.C.  479.  *  Vol.  iii  374. 

s  "  The  difficulty  has  arisen,  largely  because  the  Court  of  Criminal  Appeal  used 
language  which  has  been  construed  as  suggesting  that  the  test  of  the  condition  of  mind 
of  the  prisoner  is,  not  whether  he  was  incapable  of  forming  the  intent,  but  whether  he 
was  incapable  of  foreseeing  or  measuring  the  consequences  of  the  act,"  [1920]  A.C.  at 
pp.  503-504. 

6  It  is  said,  Kenny,  op.  cit.  61,  that  it  *'  may  produce  such  a  mistake  of  fact  as  will 
in  itself  excuse  an  otherwise  unlawful  act  "  ;  sed  quart  whether  a  mistake  so  produced, 
unless  it  negatives  the  necessary  intent,  can  or  should  have  any  effect  on  the  drunken 
man's  liability.  7  Hale  P.C.  i  c  vii. 

8  Ibid  43-44  ;  vol,  vi  101-103,  267.        9  Hale,  P.C.  i  44.  10  Vol.  iii  530-531. 


444  CRIME  AND  TORT 

extended  during  the  latter  part  of  the  seventeenth  century.  As 
thus  extended,  it  runs  as  follows  : — Whenever  any  one  of  a 
certain  limited  number  of  crimes  is  committed  by  the  wife  in  the 
presence  of  her  husband,  she  is  presumed  to  have  committed  it 
under  the  coercion  of  her  husband,  and  for  that  reason  escapes 
liability.1  Hale's  2  opinion  was  that  the  reason  for  thus  extending 
the  law,  and  allowing  coercion  to  be  presumed  from  the  mere 
presence  of  the  husband,  was  probably  "because  the  judges 
wished  to  give  to  married  women  some  sort  of  rough  equivalent 
for  the  benefit  of  clergy  enjoyed  by  their  husbands."3  But  the 
limits  of  the  rule  are  uncertain.  It  does  not  apply  to  treason  or 
murder,4  nor  to  misdemeanours  specially  connected  with  the 
management  of  the  house ;  5  and  it  can  be  rebutted  by  proof  that 
the  wife  was  the  active  partner  in  the  crime.6  Moreover,  taken  in 
connection  with  the  non-admissibility  of  this  defence  in  other 
cases,  it  may,  as  Stephen  points  out,  produce  obviously  unjust 
results.  If  a  husband,  wife,  and  their  child  of  fifteen  commit 
larceny,  though  it  be  proved  that  the  child  acted  under  threats  by 
the  father,  and  that  no  threats  were  offered  to  the  wife,  the  child 
will  be  convicted,  and  the  wife  will  escape.7 

Compulsion. — Hale  lays  it  down  that  "  in  times  of  war  and 
public  rebellion,  when  a  person  is  under  so  great  a  power,  that  he 
cannot  resist  or  avoid,  the  law  in  some  cases  allows  an  impunity 
for  parties  compelled,  or  drawn  by  fear  of  death,  to  do  some  acts 
in  themselves  capital,  which  admit  no  excuse  in  the  time  of 
peace."  8  The  defence,  therefore,  is  not  available  in  time  of  peace. 
There  are  apparently  only  two  cases  in  which  Hale's  principle  has 
ever  been  put  forward  as  a  defence.9     The  result  is  that  the  law 

1  Stephen,  Digest  of  the  Criminal  Law  Art.  30 ;  Kenny,  op.  cit.  71-72  ;  it  is  fairly 
clear  from  the  authorities  which  are  collected  by  Stephen,  op.  cit.  332-336,  that  the 
rule,  in  its  modern  form,  is  not  much  older  than  Hale;  Hale,  P.C.  i  45-46,  admits 
that  there  is  authority  against  this  form  of  it,  and  states  it  only  as  "  the  modern  prac- 
tice and  fittest  to  be  followed  " ;  it  is  probable  that  Bacon  had  something  to  do  with 
the  establishment  of  the  practice ;  he  says  in  his  Maxims  (Works  Ed.  Spedding  vii 
344)  "  where  baron  and  feme  commit  a  felony,  the  feme  can  neither  be  principal  nor 
accessory ;  because  the  law  intends  her  to  have  no  will,  in  regard  of  the  subjection  and 
obedience  she  owes  her  husband  " ;  but  this,  as  Stephen  says,  "  goes  infinitely  beyond 
his  authorities." 

2  "  Otherwise  for  the  same  felony  the  husband  may  be  saved  by  the  benefit  of 
clergy,  and  the  wife  hanged,"  P.C.  i  45-46. 

3  Stephen,  H.C.L.  ii  106 ;  it  was  only  a  rough  equivalent,  for,  as  Hale  says,  P.C. 
i  46,  "in  manslaughter  committed  jointly  by  husband  and  wife  the  husband  may  have 
his  clergy,  and  yet  the  wife  is  not  on  that  account  to  be  privileged  by  her  coverture." 

4  Hale,  P.C.  i  45. 

8  "  A  wife  may  be  indicted  together  with  her  husband,  and  condemned  to  the 
pillory  with  him  for  keeping  a  bawdy  house ;  for  this  is  an  offence  as  to  the  govern- 
ment of  the  house,  in  which  the  wife  has  a  principal  share,"  Hawkins,  P.C.  Bk.  1 
Cap.  1  §  12. 

6  R.  v.  Cruse  (1838)  8  C.  and  P.  541. 

7  H.C.L.  ii  106.  8  P.C.  i  49 ;  vol.  iii  372. 

9  R.  v.  M'Growther  (1746)  Foster,  Crown  Law  13  ;  R,  v.  Crutchley  (1831)  5  C, 
and  P.  133 ;  Stephen,  H.C.L,  ii  106, 


CRIMINAL  LIABILITY  445 

relating  to  it  is,  as  Professor  Kenny  says,1    "  both    meagre  and 
vague." 

Necessity. — That  certain  kinds  of  public  necessity  will  excuse 
what  would  otherwise  be  a  breach  of  the  law,  has  long  been  a 
recognized  principle.  Some  illustrations  of  this  principle  have 
been  worked  out  into  elaborate  rules — the  rules,  for  instance,  as 
to  the  measures  which  may  be  taken  in  self-defence,2  or  to  arrest 
criminals,2  and  the  rules  which  are  summed  up  under  the  mis- 
nomer martial  law.8  Lord  Mansfield  once  suggested  that  an 
extraordinary  case  might  arise,  in  which  imminent  danger  might 
excuse  the  deposition  of  a  colonial  governor  by  his  council ;  4  and 
his  statement  was  approved  by  the  court  in  R.  v.  Dudley. b  But 
naturally  the  limits  of  this  principle  are  and  must  be  vague  ;  and 
cases  like  that  suggested  by  Lord  Mansfield,  will  probably  be 
decided  upon  political,  rather  than  upon  strictly  legal,  considera- 
tions. In  cases  which  turn  upon  private  rather  than  on  public 
necessity  the  law  has  always  been  very  reluctant  to  admit  this 
defence.  There  are  one  or  two  dicta  in  the  sixteenth  century 
pointing  to  its  admission  in  certain  cases ; 6  but  it  is  now  settled 
that  no  private  necessity  is,  as  a  general  rule,  allowed  as  an 
excuse  for  the  commission  of  a  crime  against  some  third  person. 
A  man  who  is  assaulted  and  in  peril  of  death,  has  no  right  to  kill 
an  innocent  third  person  in  order  to  effect  his  escape ; "  and  a  man 
who  is  in  dire  necessity  for  clothes  or  food  or  drink,  has  no  right 
to  steal  to  satisfy  his  needs.8  It  is  just  possible  to  imagine 
exceptions  to  this  general  rule — but  no  case  so  far  has  occurred  in 
which  the  validity  of  such  an  exception  had  been  admitted.9  As 
Stephen  says,10  "  these  cases  cannot  be  defined  beforehand,  and 
must  be  adjudicated  upon  by  a  jury  afterwards,  the  jury  not  being 
themselves  under  the  pressure  of  the  motives  which  influenced  the 
alleged  offenders." 


1  Op.  cit.  73.  2  Vol.  iii  312-314,  377378,  598-604. 

3  Vol.  i  578  ;  vol.  vi  52-54.  *  R.  v.  Stratton  (1779)  21  S.T.  at  p.  1224. 

5  (1884)  14  Q.B.D.  at  p.  285. 

4 "  If  a  man  steal  viands  to  satisfy  his  present  hunger,  this  is  no  felony  nor 
larceny,"  Bacon,  Maxims,  Works  (Ed.  Spedding)  vii  343 ;  for  which  there  is  some 
authority  in  the  argument  of  Reniger  v.  Fogossa,  Plowden  at  p.  19. 

7  l<  If  a  man  be  desperately  assaulted  and  in  peril  of  death,  and  cannot  otherwise 
escape,  unless  to  satisfy  his  assailants'  fury  he  will  kill  an  innocent  person  then  pre- 
sent, the  fear  and  actual  force  will  not  acquit  him  of  the  crime  and  punishment  of 
murder,  if  he  commit  the  fact :  for  he  ought  rather  to  die  himself  than  kill  an  innocent," 
Hale,  P.C.  i  51 ;  R.  v.  Dudley  (1884)  14  Q.B.D.  273.  This  rule  is  not  inconsistent 
with  Bacon's  dictum,  Works  vii  344,  that,  if  a  shipwrecked  sailor  on  a  plank  thrust 
another  off  to  save  himself  from  drowning,  he  commits  no  crime ;  he  does  no  bodily 
harm  to  the  other,  and  what  he  does  is  in  self-defence ;  see  Kenny,  op.  cit.  76  n. 

8  Hale,  P.C.  i  54-55;  Bl.  Comm.  iv  31-32;  as  Blackstone  points  out,  the  poor 
law  makes  such  a  permission  quite  unnecessary. 

*  See  Kenny,  op.  cit.  76  n.  10  H.C.L.  ii  109-110. 


446  CRIME  AND  TORT 

In  these  various  ways  the  law,  starting  from  the  idea  that 
a  mens  rea  or  element  of  moral  guilt  is  a  necessary  foundation 
of  criminal  liability,  has  so  defined  and  elaborated  that  idea  in 
reference  to  various  sorts  of  crimes,  that  it  has  come  to  connote 
very  many  different  shades  of  guilt  in  different  connections.  But, 
though  mens  rea  has  thus  come  to  be  a  very  technical  conception 
with  different  technical  meanings  in  different  contexts,  it  has 
never  wholly  lost  its  natural  meaning ;  and,  because  its  natural 
meaning  has  never  been  wholly  lost  sight  of,  the  necessity  for  its 
presence,  in  some  form,  has  supplied  the  principle  upon  which 
many  of  the  circumstances,  which  will  negative  criminal  liability, 
are  based.  These,  in  their  turn,  have  been  so  developed  that 
they  have  become  the  foundation  of  different  bodies  of  technical 
doctrine ;  and  in  these  ways  a  large  part  of  our  modern  criminal 
law  has  been  developed.  We  shall  now  see  that  the  very 
different  developments  which  have  taken  place  in  the  rules  of 
civil  liability,  have  likewise  created  no  inconsiderable  part  of  our 
modern  law  of  tort. 

Civil  Liability 

During  the  mediaeval  period  the  principle  which  underlay  the 
law  as  to  civil  liability  can  be  stated  somewhat  as  follows : 1  A 
man  is  liable  for  all  the  harm  which  he  has  inflicted  upon  another 
by  his  acts,  if  what  he  has  done  comes  within  some  one  of  the 
forms  of  action  provided  by  the  law,  whether  that  harm  has  been 
inflicted  intentionally,  negligently,  or  accidentally.  A  man  acts 
at  his  peril.  This  absolute  liability  for  damage  caused  by  an  act 
which  comes  within  one  of  the  forms  of  action,  even  though  the 
damage  is  the  result  of  pure  accident,  was  restated  by  Bacon  at 
the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century ; 2  and  it  was  used  by  Hale  in  the 
seventeenth  century  to  point  the  contrast  between  criminal  and 
civil  liability.3  It  was  logically  followed  out  (i)  in  respect  to  the 
defences  open  to  a  defendant,  and  (ii)  in  respect  to  a  person's 
liability  for  the  acts  of  his  servants,  (i)  A  defendant  could  escape 
from  liability  if  he  could  prove  that  his  act  was,  in  the  circum- 
stances, permitted  by  the  law,  either  in  the  public  interest,  or 
in  the  necessary  defence  of  his  person  or  rights  of  property ;  or 
that  the  act,  which  was  the  immediate  cause  of  damage,  was  done, 
not  by  himself,  but  by  the  plaintiff;  or  that  it  was  unavoidable  by 
reason  of  an  'act  of  God.'4  (ii)  As  a  defendant  was  liable  only 
for  his  acts,  he  could  not  as  a  rule  be  held  liable  for  any  tort 
committed  by  his   servant,   which   he   had  not  commanded  or 

1  See  vol.  iii  375-377.  2  Ibid  376-377. 

s  Ibid  375.  *  Ibid  377"379»  380. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  447 

ratified ;  for  unless  he  had  commanded  or  ratified  it,  it  could 
not  be  said  to  be  his  act1 

It  is  clear  that  this  principle  of  civil  liability  rests  ultimately 
upon  a  very  primitive  basis.  It  obviously  takes  account,  not  of 
the  moral  shortcomings  of  the  defendant,  but  only  of  the  loss 
of  the  plaintiff;  and  this  characteristic  is  reminiscent  of  the  days 
when  the  compensation  payable  was  regarded,  not  as  a  penalty 
for  wrongdoing,  but  as  a  means  whereby  the  plaintiff  was  in- 
duced to  forego  his  right  to  take  revenge.2  But,  as  in  other 
cases,  the  precocious  development  of  English  law  gave  an  un- 
usually long  life  to  this  principle,  because  it  had  been  made  the 
basis  of  a  technical  system  of  fixed  rules.  The  result  is  that 
some  of  the  rules,  to  which  it  gave  rise,  long  remained  a  part  of 
English  law ;  and  the  principle  itself  was  unsuccessfully  invoked 
as  a  ground  of  liability  as  late  as  1891.3 

It  was  during  this  period  that  the  principle  began  to  be 
Undermined.  In  the  first  place,  a  certain  number  of  the  new 
torts,  which  were  springing  up  in  this  period,  were  based  on  some 
form  of  wrongful  intent — they  were  essentially  malicious  wrongs. 
In  the  second  place,  in  a  very  much  larger  number  of  cases  the 
courts  were  beginning  to  base  the  defendant's  liability,  not  on 
the  fact  that  he  had  acted,  but  on  the  fact  that  he  had  acted 
negligently,  to  the  damage  of  the  plaintiff.  Both  these  causes 
tended  firstly  to  restrict,  and  then  to  encroach^upon,  the  sphere 
of  the  mediaeval  principle.  But  the  mediaeval  principle,  though 
greatly  restricted  in  its  sphere,  did  not  wholly  disappear.  A 
place  is  still  found  for  it  in  modern  law ;  but  it  is  a  very  different 
place  from  that  which  it  occupied  in  the  mediaeval  law ;  and  it  is 
founded  on  very  different  principles.  In  the  third  place,  at  the 
close  of  the  seventeenth  century,  the  beginnings  of  the  modern 
doctrine  of  Employers'  Liability  entirely  changed  the  mediaeval 
principles  relating  to  this  part  of  the  law. 

I  propose  to  relate  the  history  of  these  changes  under  the 
following  heads: — (1)  the  conceptions  of  wrongful  intention  and 
negligence  as  bases  of  liability;  (2)  the  place  of  the  mediaeval 
principle  of  liability  in  modern  law;  and  (3)  the  doctrine  of 
Employers'  Liability. 

(1)  The  conceptions  of  wrongful  intention  and  negligence  as 
bases  of  liability. 

The  part  played  by  wrongful  intention  in  the  law  of  tort  is  and 
always  has  been  small.      It  has  come  to  be  an  essential  element  in 

1  Vol.  iii  382-385.  a  Vol.  ii  50-52. 

*  Stanley  v.  Powell  [1891]  1  Q.B.  86. 


448  CRIME  AND  TORT 

the  tort  of  deceit,1  of  malicious  prosecution,2  and  of  defamation, 
when  the  words  complained  of  were  spoken  on  an  occasion  which 
is  protected  by  a  qualified  privilege.3  We  have  seen  that  at  one 
time  the  courts  laid  it  down  that  malice  was  always  an  essential 
element  in  the  tort  of  defamation.  But  this  malice  was  always 
implied  by  the  law  from  the  making  of  the  defamatory  statement  ; 
and  it  is  now  recognized  that  it  is  not  an  essential  element  in  the 
tort.4  A  very  similar  development  has  taken  place  in  respect  of 
the  new  tort  of  persuasion  to  break  a  contract  created  by  Lumley 
v.  Gye}  It  was  at  one  time  thought  that  its  essence  was  the 
malicious  persuasion  to  break  a  contract.6  But  that  idea  has 
been  ruled  by  the  House  of  Lords  to  be  erroneous.7  Just  as  the 
essence  of  the  tort  of  defamation  is  the  publication  of  untrue  de- 
famatory statements  without  just  cause  or  excuse,  so  the  essence 
of  this  new  tort  created  by  the  case  of  Lumley  v.  Gye  is  the  fact 
that  a  breach  of  contract  has  been  knowingly  and  wilfully  procured 
without  just  cause  or  excuse.  The  part,  therefore,  played  by  the 
element  of  wrongful  intention  in  creating  civil  liability  is  very  small ; 
and,  except  in  the  case  of  those  torts  in  which  the  existence  of 
such  an  intention  is  an  essential  factor,  the  fact  that  such  an  intention 
exists  will  not  make  an  act,  otherwise  lawful,  tortious.  With 
respect  to  the  exercise  of  rights  of  property  this  proposition  was 
affirmed  by  the  House  of  Lords  in  1895,8  and  with  respect  to  the 
exercise  of  other  rights  in  1 898  ; 9  and  there  can  be  little  doubt 
but  that  it  is  historically  sound.10  We  have  seen  that,  in  the 
mediaeval  period,  the  courts  refused  to  base  civil  liability  upon 
intent — "the  thought  of  man  is  not  triable";  and,  later,  wrongful 
intent  was  only  partially  admitted  as  a  ground  of  liability  in  the 
case  of  certain  specified  torts.  The  contrary  decision  would  have 
given  to  wrongful  intent  a  far  more  extensive  effect  in  creating 
civil  liability,  than  was  warranted  by  any  of  the  previous  decisions. 
It  would,  in  effect,  have  given  to  it  a  different,  but  almost  as  ex- 
tensive an  effect,  as  negligence  has  come  to  have  in  the  creation 
of  this  liability. 

1  Vol.  iii  408  ;  above  426.  2  Above  391. 

3  Above  372,  375.  4  Above  374-375. 

5  (1853)  2  E.  and  B.  216  ;  for  the  development  of  this  tort  see  vol.  iv  383-385  ; 
above  431. 

6  Bowen  v.  Hall  (1881)  6  Q.B.D.  333  ;  Temperton  v.  Russell  [1893]  1  Q.B.  715. 

7  Allen  v.  Flood  [1898]  A.C.  1  ;  at  p.  121  Lord  Herschell  said,  "A  study  of  the 
case  of  Lttmley  v.  Gye  has  satisfied  me  that  in  that  case  the  majority  of  the  Court  re- 
garded the  circumstance  that  what  the  defendant  procured  was  a  breach  of  contract  as 
the  essence  of  the  cause  of  action.  It  is  true  that  the  word  maliciously  was  found  in 
the  declaration,  the  validity  of  which  was  then  under  consideration  ;  but  I  do  not  think 
the  learned  judges  regarded  the  allegation  as  involving  the  necessity  of  proving  an  evil 
motive  on  the  part  of  the  defendant,  but  merely  as  implying  that  the  defendant  had 
wilfully  and  knowingly  procured  a  breach  of  contract." 

8  Mayor  of  Bradford  v.  Pickles  [1895]  A.C.  587. 

9  Allen  v.  Flood  [1898]  A.C.  1 ;  and  see  Lord  Herschell's  statement  at  p.  124. 
Ju  See  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  157-158. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  449 

We  have  seen  that  the  idea  that  civil  liability  was  based  upon 
negligence  was  unknown  in  the  mediaeval  common  law.  The 
central  idea  of  the  mediaeval  common  law,  was  that  civil  liability 
was  based  upon  an  act  causing  damage,  if  that  act  fell  within  one 
of  the  causes  of  action  provided  for  by  the  law.1  This  idea  obviously 
excludes  any  direct  reference  to  negligence  as  a  cause  of  liability. 
But  we  have  seen  that  the  conception  of  negligence  is  latent  in  the 
principle  that  a  man  is  only  liable  for  the  damage  which  is  the 
proximate  consequence  of  his  act.'2  The  fact  that  the  conception 
of  negligence  is  latent  in  this  principle  was  naturally  emphasized 
by  the  growth  of  actions  on  the  case,  in  which  the  damage  flowing 
from  the  act  was  the  gist  of  the  action.  In  an  ordinary  trespass, 
in  which  a  forcible  act  directly  caused  damage  to  the  plaintiff's 
person  or  property,  the  connection  between  the  act  and  the  damage 
was  generally  obvious.  But,  when  the  damage  was  not  the  direct 
result  of  the  defendant's  act,  it  was  necessary  to  show  that  it  was 
its  proximate  consequence.  To  a  modern  lawyer  it  would  seem 
that  the  obvious  method  of  ascertaining  whether  or  not  the  damage 
is  the  proximate  consequence  of  the  defendant's  act,  is  to  enquire 
whether  the  defendant  foresaw  or  ought  to  have  foreseen  such 
damage  as  a  necessary  consequence  of  his  act ;  to  rule  that,  if  he 
foresaw  it  or  ought  to  have  foreseen  it,  he  was  negligent ;  and  that 
because  he  was  thus  negligent  he  is  liable.  But  this  way  of  look- 
ing at  the  problem  is  essentially  modern,  and  it  has  only  become 
possible  as  the  result  of  a  long  historical  development,  the  outlines 
of  which  I  must  here  try  to  trace.3 

When  the  actions  on  the  case  first  began  to  be  developed,  the 
mediaeval  notions  as  to  the  basis  of  civil  liability  were  engrained 
in  the  minds  of  the  lawyers.  If  they  had  been  asked  why  an  act 
directly  causing  damage  to  the  plaintiff  gave  rise  to  liability  en- 
forceable in  an  action  of  trespass,  they  would  have  said  that  such 
an  act  gave  rise  to  liability  because  it  was  unlawful.  The  same 
reasoning  was  applied  to  some  of  the  earliest  actions  on  the  case. 
An  act  which  caused  damage  in  certain  specified  ways  was  regarded 
as  giving  rise  to  liability  because  it  was  an  unlawful  act.  Thus 
inn-keepers,  common  carriers,  smiths,  surgeons,  taverners,  vintners, 
or  butchers,  could  be  made  liable  in  an  action  on  the  case  if,  as  the 
result  of  want  of  care,  skill,  or  honesty,  the  persons  who  had  come 
into  business  relations  with  them  were  damaged.4     We  should  say 

1  Vol.  iii  375-377-  2  Ibid  379-3&°- 

3  The  best  historical  account  of  the  general  development  of  the  conception  of 
negligence  is  to  be  found  in  Street,  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  i  chap,  xiii ;  the 
historical  matter  in  Holmes,  Common  Law  Lecture  III  is  mainly  concerned  with  de- 
velopment of  the  idea  in  the  sphere  of  trespass,  which  is  dealt  with  below  453-458  ;  on 
this  latter  point  see  also  Wigmore,  Responsibility  for  Tortious  Acts,  Essays  A.A.L.H. 
iii  505-507 ;  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  142-147. 

*  Vol.  iii  385-386. 
VOL.   VIII.— 29 


450  CRIME  AND  TORT 

at  the  present  day  that  they  were  liable  for  fraud  or  negligence. 
In  the  Middle  Ages  they  were  said  to  be  liable  "by  the  common 
custom  of  the  realm  " — that  is  they  were  liable  because  their  conduct 
was  regarded  by  the  law  as  wrongful.  Similarly,  we  have  seen 
that  any  person  was  liable  in  an  action  on  the  case  if,  having  under- 
taken to  do  something  for  another,  he  had  done  it  so  badly  that 
that  other  was  damaged.1  We  should  say  at  the  present  day  that 
such  liability  was  founded  on  a  breach  of  contract.  In  the  Middle 
Ages  it  was  considered  to  be  a  liability  for  conduct  which,  by 
reason  of  the  undertaking,  was  regarded  by  the  law  as  wrongful.2 
But,  as  damage  was  the  gist  of  the  action  on  the  case,  the  court, 
in  coming  to  a  conclusion  whether  or  not  a  defendant  could  be 
made  liable  in  such  an  action,  was  bound  to  consider  whether  or 
not  the  damage  alleged  could  be  said  to  be  a  sufficiently  proximate 
consequence  of  the  defendant's  act  to  entail  liability;  and  this 
question  could  only  be  answered  by  asking  whether  any  ordinarily 
prudent  man  would  have  foreseen  that  damage  would  probably 
result  from  his  act.  Thus  the  courts  were  gradually  familiarized 
with  the  conception  of  negligence ;  and,  since  the  idea  of  negli- 
gence was  brought  before  them  in  this  way,  three  consequences 
followed.  In  the  first  place,  they  naturally,  from  the  first,  adopted 
the  objective  standard  of  the  ordinarily  prudent  man ;  for  they 
were  not  trying  to  determine  whether  this  or  that  defendant  had 
been  negligent,  but  whether,  having  regard  to  what  any  ordinarily 
prudent  man  would  have  foreseen,  a  particular  damage,  flowing 
from  a  given  defendant's  acts,  was  a  sufficiently  proximate  conse- 
quence of  those  acts  to  entail  liability.  This  principle  was  not 
indeed  formally  laid  down  till  1837  ;3  but,  as  Sir  F.  Pollock  says, 
the  idea  "  pervades  the  mass  of  our  authorities  "  ; 4  and  it  pervades 
them,  because  this  manner  of  regarding  negligence  was  necessitated 
by  the  way  in  which  the  conception  came  into  the  common  law. 
In  the  second  place,  the  courts  necessarily  regarded  negligence  as 
being  correlative  to  the  existence  of  a  duty  not  to  harm  the 
plaintiff  in  the  manner  of  which  he  was  complaining ; 5  for,  until 
such  a  duty  had  been  established,  the  mere  fact  that  the  defendant 
had  harmed  the  plaintiff  could  give  rise  to  no  cause  of  action  ;  and 
therefore  the  enquiry  whether  the  damage  was  the  proximate  con- 

1  Vol.  Hi  386,  429-431. 

3  Note  that  Blackstone,  Comm.  iii  163-165,  states  the  mediaeval  rules,  but  classes 
them  under  those  "  presumptive  undertakings  or  assumpsits"  arising  from  the  "  general 
implication  and  intendment  of  the  courts  of  judicature  that  every  man  hath  engaged  to 
perform  what  his  duty  or  justice  requires  " — at  that  date  the  idea  of  contract  or  quasi- 
contract  was  in  the  ascendant ;  and  even  at  the  present  day,  as  Mr.  Street  points  out, 
op.  cit.  i  87,  the  subject  of  negligence  is  as  important  in  the  law  of  contract  as  in  the 
law  of  tort. 

3Vaughan  v.  Menlove  (1837)  3  Bing.  N.C.  468. 

*  Torts  (12th  ed.)  444.  5  Ibid  439-440. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  451 

sequence  of  the  defendant's  act  would  be  unnecessary.  In  the 
third  place,  we  get  that  distinguishing  characteristic  of  the  law  of 
tort,  as  compared  with  the  law  of  contract,  that  "the  primary 
question  of  liability  may  itself  depend  ...  on  the  nearness  or  re- 
moteness of  the  harm  complained  of.  Except  where  we  have  an 
absolute  duty  and  an  act  which  manifestly  violates  it,  no  clear  line 
can  be  drawn  between  the  rule  of  liability  and  the  rule  of  com- 
pensation."1 We  shall  see,  however,  that  a  clear  line  has  been 
drawn  by  the  Court  of  Appeal  between  the  principle  upon  which 
liability  to  compensate  is  based,  and  the  principle  upon  which  the 
amount  of  the  compensation  is  assessed.  The  question  whether 
the  damage  was  sufficiently  probable  for  a  reasonable  man  to  have 
anticipated  is  relevant  in  determining  the  question  of  negligence — 
that  is  of  liability  to  compensate  :  it  is  not  relevant  in  determining 
the  measure  of  damages.  - 

There  are  many  proofs  that,  during  the  sixteenth  and  seven- 
teenth centuries,  the  constant  need  to  inquire  whether,  in  any  given 
case,  the  damage  complained  of  by  the  plaintiff  was  a  sufficiently 
proximate  consequence  of  the  act  of  the  defendant,  was  familiariz- 
ing the  courts  with  the  idea  that  in  a  large  number  of  cases  liability 
was  grounded  upon  negligence.  We  have  seen  that,  in  the  field 
of  crime,  the  line  between  murder  and  manslaughter  was  often  fixed 
by  reference  to  the  degree  of  negligence  shown  ; 3  and  the  rule  that 
a  defendant  was  not  liable  for  damage  done  by  an  ordinarily  tame 
animal,  unless  scienter  was  proved,  involves  the  idea  that  liability 
is  founded  upon  negligence.4  But,  in  the  sphere  of  tort,  it  seems 
that  the  conception  was  at  first  applied  where  the  duty  owed  by 
the  defendant  to  the  plaintiff  arose  out  of  some  contractual,  quasi- 
contractual,  or  proprietary  relation.  Thus,  in  1601,  Coke  laid  it 
down  that  "  where  a  man  delivers  a  horse  to  another  to  keep  safe, 
the  defendant  equunt  ilium  tarn  negligenter  custodivit,  quod  ob  de- 
fectum bonce  custodiae  interiit,  the  action  on  the  case  lies  for  this 
breach  of  trust;  so  if  my  shepherd,  whom  I  trust  with  my  sheep, 
and  by  his  negligence  they  be  drowned,  or  otherwise  perish,  an 
action  upon  the  case  lies."  5  Similarly,  we  have  seen  that  it  was 
well  settled  that  persons,  like  smiths  or  innkeepers,  who  were  bound 
by  law  to  exercise  their  callings  skilfully,  were  under  a  duty  of  a 
delictual  or  quasi-contractual  nature,  if  they  caused  damage  by 
their  negligence.6     A  like  principle  was  applied   in  the  sphere  of 

1  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  30. 

2  Re  Polemis  [1921]  3  K.B.  560  ;  below  462-464.  3  Above  436. 

*  This  rule  was  well  established  by  the  decisions  of  the  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries,  see  Anon.  (1537)  Dyer  25b,  29a ;  Mitten  v.  Faudiye  (1625)  Popbam  161  ; 
Boulton  v.  Banks  (1632)  Cro.  Car.  204  ;  Kinnion  v.  Davies  (1637)  'bid  4^7  1  Jenkins 
v.  Turner  (1697)  1  Ld.  Raym.  109. 

5  The  Countess  of  Shrewsbury's  Case  5  Co.  Rep.  14a. 

*  Vol.  Hi  385-386,  448  ;  above  89. 


452  CRIME  AND  TORT 

property  law.  In  1674  it  was  held  that,  where  the  defendants 
were  bound  by  prescription  to  maintain  a  fence,  and  by  reason  of 
their  negligence  they  failed  to  maintain  it,  so  that  the  plaintiff's 
mare  got  through  the  gap  and  was  drowned,  the  plaintiff  could 
recover  in  an  action  on  the  case.1 

We  have  seen,  however,  that  the  law  made  certain  bailees, 
to  whom  possession  of  goods  had  been  entrusted,  liable,  even 
though  they  had  not  been  negligent.  These  rules  were,  as  we 
have  seen,  due  mainly  to  the  position  which  the  law  attributed  to 
possessors  as  such,  and  partly  to  the  fact  that  they  had  become 
fixed  before  the  common  law  had  attained  the  conception  of 
negligence.2  But  it  is  clear  from  Southcotes  Casez  that  the  court, 
in  the  light  of  the  new  conception  that  liability  should  be  founded 
on  negligence,  was  beginning  to  think  that  they  were  hard  rules.4 
They  were  not  extended  to  the  newer  varieties  of  bailees ; 5  and  we 
have  seen  that  Coke  advised  that  they  should  be  evaded  by  making 
special  contracts  as  to  the  measure  of  liability.6  The  manner  in 
which  Holt,  C.J.,  in  the  case  of  Coggs  v.  BemardyLput  the  law  as 
to  bailees  on  its  modern  basis,  and  applied  to  their  liabilities  the 
Roman  rules  as  to  negligence,  which  he  had  taken  from  Bracton, 
is  the  best  proof  that,  at  the  beginning  of  the  eighteenth  century, 
the  judges  were  coming  to  the  conclusion  that  negligence  should 
generally  be  regarded  as  a  basis  of  liability ;  and  that,  in  the  ab- 
sence of  negligence,  no  liability  should  as  a  rule  be  imputed.  In 
fact,  that  decision  gave  effect  to  a  tendency  in  this  direction,  which 
had  been  felt  in  different  ways  throughout  the  sixteenth  and  seven- 
teenth centuries.8  But  even  then  two  survivals  of  the  older  law 
were  still  left — the  innkeeper  and  the  common  carrier.  The  inn- 
keeper is  still  absolutely  liable,  as  he  was  liable  in  the  Middle 
Ages,9  by  the  common  custom  of  the  realm,  for  the  safe  custody 
of  the  goods  of  his  guests.10  The  common  carrier,11  common  hoy- 
man,  or  master  of  a  ship,  being  persons  "that  exercise  a  public 
employment,"  were  bound  to  "  answer  for  the  goods  at  all  events," 
except  as  against  acts  of  God  and  the  king's  enemies.12     But  the 

1  Anon.  1  Vent.  264-265  ;  Star  v.  Rookesby  (171 1)  1  Salk.  335. 

2  Vol.  vii  450-451.  3  (1601)  4  Co.  Rep.  83b. 

4  Note  that  in  Gelley  v.  Clerk  (1607)  Cro.  Jac.  188  the  innkeeper's  liability  as  a 
bailee  of  his  guests'  goods  was  limited  to  those  who  were  actually  staying  in  his  inn  as 
guests. 

5  "  If  a  factor  (although  he  has  wages  and  salary)  does  all  that  which  he  by  his 
industry  can  do,  he  shall  be  discharged  .  .  .  but  a  ferryman,  common  innkeeper,  or 
carrier,  who  takes  hire,  ought  to  keep  the  goods  in  their  custody  safely,  and  shall  not 
be  discharged,  if  they  are  stolen  by  thieves,"  4  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  84a. 

8  Ibid ;  above  259.  7  (1704)  2  Ld.  Raym.  909  ;  vol.  vii  45^. 

8  Above  452-453.  9  Vol.  iii  385-386. 

10  Cayle's  Case  (1584)  8  Co.  Rep.  32a  ;  (1624)  Hutton  at  p.  100  ;  Robins  and  Co. 
v.  Gray  [1895]  2  Q.B.  at  p.  504  per  Lord  Esher,  M.R. 

11  For  the  detailed  history  see  Holmes,  Common  Law  197-205. 

12  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  pp.  917-918. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  453 

exemption  of  other  bailees  entrusted  with  the  possession  of  goods 
from  this  absolute  liability,  had  destroyed  the  older  reasons  for  the 
rule  ; l  and  its  application  to  these  persons,  as  an  exceptional  rule, 
was  based  by  Holt,  C.J.,  on  public  policy.2  As  applied  to  common 
carriers,  it  was  accepted  by  Lord  Mansfield  ; 3  and  it  is  still  part 
of  the  law.  But  even  in  Holt's  day  it  was  clearly  regarded  as  an 
exceptional  rule  which  required  to  be  justified. 

Since  the  law  had  reached  this  stage  by  the  end  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  it  is  not  surprising  to  find  that  a  further  step  was 
then  taken.  "The  conception,"  as  Mr.  Street  puts  it,4  "of 
common  law  liability  for  negligence  was  so  extended  as  to  make 
one  liable,  in  an  action  on  the  case,  for  damage  flowing  from  the 
negligent  performance  of  his  own  projects  and  undertakings,  un- 
connected with  the  duty  arising  from  statute,  public  calling, 
bailment,  or  prescription."  This  extension  was  certainly  made 
in  1676  in  the  case  of  Mitchil  v.  Ales  tree}  In  that  case  the 
defendant  had  brought  an  unruly  horse  into  Lincoln's  Inn  Fields 
for  the  purpose  of  breaking  him.  The  horse  escaped  from  the 
defendant,  and  damaged  the  plaintiff.  The  court  held  that  the 
plaintiff  could  recover.  "  It  was  the  defendant's  fault  to  bring  a 
wild  horse  into  such  a  place,  where  mischief  might  probably  be 
done,  by  reason  of  the  concourse  of  people.  Lately,  in  this  Court, 
an  action  was  brought  against  a  butcher,  who  had  made  an  ox 
run  from  his  stall  and  gored  the  plaintiff;  and  this  was  alleged  in 
the  declaration  to  be  in  default  of  penning  him."  And  Wylde,  J., 
said,  "  if  a  man  hath  an  unruly  horse  in  his  stable,  and  leaves  open 
the  stable  door,  whereby  the  horse  goes  forth  and  does  mischief; 
an  action  lies  against  the  master." 

But,  just  as  it  was  difficult  to  apply  this  new  conception  of 
negligence  to  certain  kinds  of  bailees,  whose  position  had  been 
defined  by  older  rules  of  law,  so  it  was  difficult  to  apply  it  in  cases 
where  the  act  complained  of  was  a  direct  act  of  violence.  Such 
an  act  was  generally  a  trespass,  and  therefore  an  unlawful  act ; 
and  if  it  was  an  unlawful  act,  there  could  be  no  question  of  the 
defendant's  liability.  But  such  an  act  may  be  the  result  of  a 
perfectly  lawful  act  done  purely  accidentally ;  and  we  have  seen 
that,  as  late  as  the  end  of  the  sixteenth  century,  Bacon  restated 
the  mediaeval  rule  that,  even  in  such  a  case,  the  person  doing  the 

1  Vol.  vii  452-453. 

*  "  This  is  a  politic  establishment,  contrived  by  the  policy  of  the  law,  for  the  safety 
of  all  persons,  the  necessity  of  whose  affairs  oblige  them  to  trust  these  sorts  of  persons, 
that  they  may  be  safe  in  their  ways  of  dealing  ;  for  else  these  carriers  might  have  an 
opportunity  of  undoing  all  persons  that  had  any  dealings  with  them,  by  combining  with 
thieves  etc.,  and  yet  doing  it  in  such  a  clandestine  manner,  as  would  not  be  possible  to 
be  discovered,"  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  918. 

3  Forward  v.  Pittard  (1785)  1  T.R.  27. 

*  Foundations  of  Legal  Liability  i  189.  s  1  Vent.  295. 


454  CRIME  AND  TORT 

act  was  liable.1  In  fact,  right  down  to  the  nineteenth  century, 
there  is  a  chain  of  authority  in  which  the  mediaeval  rule  is  stated 
and  relied  on.  Thus  in  1617,  in  the  case  of  Weaver  v.  Ward,2 
the  same  distinction  as  that  which  Bacon  drew  between  civil  and 
criminal  liability  was  drawn,  and  it  was  said  that  "no  man  shall 
be  excused  of  a  trespass  .  .  .  except  it  may  be  judged  utterly 
without  his  fault."  In  1681,  in  the  case  of  Lambert  v.  Besseyf 
the  rule  that  "  in  all  civil  acts  the  law  doth  not  so  much  regard 
the  intent  of  the  actor,  as  the  loss  and  damage  of  the  party 
suffering,"  is  repeated;  and  Brian's  dictum  that,  "if  a  man  assault 
me,  and  I  lift  up  my  staff  to  defend  myself,  and  in  lifting  it  up  hit 
another,  an  action  lies  by  that  person,  and  yet  I  did  a  lawful 
thing,"  was  also  repeated — a  dictum  again  repeated  and  approved 
by  Blackstone,  J.,  in  Scott  v.  Shepherd}  In  1682,  in  the  case  of 
Dickenson  v.  Watson,5  in  an  action  by  the  plaintiff  against  the 
defendant  for  wounding  him  with  his  pistol,  a  plea  that  the 
defendant  was  emptying  his  pistol  in  a  vacant  place,  and  that  the 
plaintiff  had  crossed  the  line  of  fire  unknown  to  the  plaintiff,  was 
held  bad  ;  for  in  trespass  the  defendant  shall  not  be  excused  with- 
out an  avoidable  necessity,  which  is  not  shewn  here."  In  1700 
the  same  view  was  urged  in  argument  in  the  case  of  Mason  v. 
Keeling-/'  and  in  1724  it  was  apparently  held  that  trespass  lay 
for  a  merely  accidental  hurt.7  In  1783  it  was  used  in  argument 
by  Erskine,  as  Bacon  had  used  it,  to  illustrate  the  difference 
between  criminal  and  civil  liability.8  In  1799  this  thesis  was 
maintained  in  argument  in  the  case  of  Ogle  v.  Barnes  ; 9  and  in 
1803,  m  tne  case  of  Leame  v.  Bray,10  it  was  restated  by  Grose,  J., 
"  Looking  into  all  the  cases  from  the  Year  Book  in  the  21  H.  7, 
down  to  the  latest  decision  on  the  subject,  I  find  the  principle  to 
be,  that  if  the  injury  be  done  by  the  act  of  the  party  himself  at  the 
time,  or  he  be  the  immediate  cause  of  it,  though  it  happen 
accidentally  or  by  misfortune,  yet  he  is  answerable  in  trespass." 
There  was  a  ruling  to  the  same  effect  in  1823  in  the  case  of 
Wakeman  v.  Robinson  ;n  and  in  1868,  in  the  case  of  Ry lands  v. 
Fletcher?*  Lord  Cranworth  approved  of  the  reasoning  of  Sir  T. 
Raymond  in  Lambert  v.  Bessey,13  which,  as  we  have  seen,  restated 
the  mediaeval  principle.  In  1891,  in  the  case  of  Stanley  v. 
Powell,1*  the  view  that  a  man  may  be  liable  for  a  purely  accidental 


I  Vol.  iii  376-377.                 2  Hob.  134.  3  Th.  Raym.  at  pp.  422,  423. 
4  (i773)  2  W.  Bl.  at  p.  896.  B  T.  Jones  205. 

6 12  Mod.  at  pp.  332-333.  "'  Underwood  v.  Hewson  1  Str.  596. 

8  The  Dean  of  St.  Asaph's  Case  21  S.T.  at  p.  1022,  cited  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.) 
142. 

9  8  T.R.  at  p.  190.  10  3  East  at  p.  600. 

II  1  Bing.  at  p.  214.  12  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  at  p.  341. 
Vi  (1681)  Th.  Raym.  421.  M  [1891]  1  Q.B.  86. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  455 

trespass  to  the  person  was  put  forward  in  argument,  and  finally 
overruled. 

It  would,  however,  be  misleading  to  think  that  the  lawyers,  as 
late  as  the  nineteenth  century,  were  prepared  to  hold  that  direct 
damage,  caused  by  an  unavoidable  accident  in  the  doing  of  a 
lawful  act,  would  expose  to  liability.  We  shall  see  that  some  of 
these  dicta  were  qualified  in  a  way  which  shows  that  the  new 
conception,  that  liability  should  be  based  on  some  moral  short- 
coming, was  making  its  influence  felt  in  the  sphere  of  trespass.1 
Others  were  contained  in  dissenting  judgments,2  or  only  in 
argument.3  Others  were  said  in  the  course  of  discussions  as  to 
whether  trespass  or  case  was  the  proper  form  of  action — that  is  in 
cases  in  which  the  mind  of  the  court  was  not  addressed  to  this 
specific  point4  Lord  Cran worth's  approval  of  the  dictum  in 
Lambert  v.  Bessey  was  confined  to  cases  of  the  type  of  Rylands  v. 
Fletcher,  which,  as  we  shall  see,  are  governed  substantially  by  the 
mediaeval  principle  of  liability.5  Nevertheless,  as  a  matter  of 
historical  fact,  these  dicta  do,  it  seems  to  me,  truly  represent  the 
mediaeval  view  as  to  liability.  But  that  mediaeval  view  was  too 
narrow ;  and  both  the  ethical  ideas  and  the  social  needs  of 
modern  times  made  it  necessary  that  it  should  be  modified. 

The  earliest  way  in  which  this  modification  was  effected  was 
foreshadowed  in  the  mediaeval  period.  It  was,  as  we  have  seen, 
admitted  that  '  the  act  of  God '  or  inevitable  necessity  would  ex- 
cuse.6 Much  was  made  of  this  in  the  later  cases ;  and  in  some  of 
them  the  way  was  prepared  for  later  developments,  by  statements 
that,  if  the  defendant  could  prove  inevitable  necessity,  he  was 
not  liable,  because  he  was  not  negligent  Thus,  in  the  case  of 
Weaver  v.  Ward,1  the  court  said  that  the  defendant  might  have 
succeeded,  if  he  "had  said  that  the  plaintiff  ran  across  his  piece 
when  it  was  discharging,  or  had  set  forth  the  case  with  the 
circumstances,  so  as  it  had  appeared  to  the  court  that  it  had  been 
inevitable,  and  that  the  defendant  had  committed  no  negligence 
to  give  occasion  to  the  hurt "  ;  and  there  is  a  long  line  of  cases 
in  which  it  was  held  that  unavoidable  necessity  was  a  good 
defence.  Thus  in  1696,  in  the  case  of  Gibbons  v.  Pepper,*  it  was 
held  that  if  the  defendant  had  pleaded  not  guilty,  and  had  given 
in  evidence  facts  which  showed  that  the  damage  was  the  result  of 
an  inevitable  accident,   "this  matter   might  have  acquitted  him 

1  E.g.  Weaver  v.  Ward  (1617)  Hob.  134. 

8  E.g.  Lambert  v.  Bessey  (1681)  Th.  Raym.  421 ;  Scott  v.  Shepherd  (1773)  2  W. 
Bl.  892. 

3  Above  454  nn.  6,  8,  9,  14.  *  E.g.  Leame  v.  Bray  (1803)  3  East  593. 

5  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  at  p.  341 — "  this  is  the  principle  of  law  applicable  to  cases  like 
the  present" ;  I  do  not  think  that  his  dictum  can  be  given,  as  Mr.  Beven  gives  it, 
Negligence  i  557,  any  more  general  application. 

s  Vol.  iii  380-382.  7  (1617)  Hob.  134.  8  1  Ld.  Raym.  38. 


456  CRIME  AND  TORT 

upon  the  evidence."  In  1767,  in  the  case  of  Eeckwith  v.  Skordike,1 
the  court  clearly  thought  that  an  involuntary  accident  could  not 
expose  to  liability;  and  in  1823  Dallas,  C.J.,  ruled2  that,  "if  the 
accident  happened  entirely  without  default  on  the  part  of  the 
defendant  or  blame  imputable  to  him,  the  action  (trespass)  does 
not  lie."  There  is  a  series  of  cases  from  the  first  half  of  the 
nineteenth  century,  in  which  it  was  held  that,  in  an  action  of 
trespass,  matters  of  excuse  must  be  specially  pleaded,8  which 
obviously  shows  that  such  matters  of  excuse,  if  proved,  would  be  a 
good  defence. 

This  expansion  of  the  idea  of  an  unavoidable  or  inevitable 
necessity  which,  in  effect  made  the  act  involuntary,  was,  I  think, 
the  main  line  of  reasoning  along  which  the  law  was  developed. 
But  it  was  not  the  only  line.  (i)  In  certain  cases,  in  which  a 
defendant  was  sued  for  trespass  committed  by  his  animals,  it  was 
held  that,  if  he  had  done  all  he  could  to  restrain  them,  he  was 
not  guilty.  Thus  in  1625,  in  the  case  of  Mitten  v.  Faudrye^  the 
defendant  had  chased  trespassing  sheep  belonging  to  the  plaintiff 
out  of  his  land  with  a  dog,  and  the  dog  had  further  pursued  them 
and  damaged  them.  The  plaintiff  brought  trespass ;  and  it  was 
held  that,  as  the  defendant  had  done  his  best  to  call  in  his  dog, 
he  was  not  liable.  Moreover,  Dodderidge,  J.,  laid  it  down  in  that 
case  that  if  a  man  was  "driving cattle  through  a  town,  and  one  of 
them  goes  into  another  man's  house,  and  he  follows  him,  trespass 
does  not  lie  for  this,  because  it  was  involuntary."  5  We  have  seen 
that  in  the  fifteenth  century  liability  for  damage  caused  by  cattle 
so  driven  was  only  negatived,  when  the  plaintiff's  omission  to  fulfil  a 
legal  duty  to  fence  was  the  cause  of  the  damage ; 6  and  it  would  seem 
that  the  law  was  the  same  in  179 5/  Probably,  therefore,  Dodderidge 
stated  the  law  too  widely  for  his  own  day.8  His  statement  has, 
however,  come  to  be  substantially  correct.9  But  it  is  now  based, 
as  McCardie,  J.,  has  pointed  out,10  on  the  much  broader  principle 
stated  by  Lord  Blackburn  in  River  Wear  Commissioners  v- 
Adamson,n  that  property  adjoining  a  highway  is  liable  to  be  in- 

I  4  Burr,  at  pp.  2093-2094.  2  Wakeman  v.  Robinson  1  Bing.  at  p.  215. 

3  Milman  v.  Dolwell  (1820)  2  Camp.  378  ;  Knapp  v.  Salsbury  (1810)  ibid  500  ; 
Boss  v.  Litton  (1832)  5  C.  and  P.  407;  Cotterill  v.  Starkey  (1837)  8  C.  and  P.  at  pp. 
694-695. 

4  Popham  161.  5  Ibid  at  p.  162. 

6  Y.B.  10  Ed.  IV.  Pasch.  pi.  ig  ;  cited  vol.  iii  378. 

7  Dovaston  v.  Payne  2  Hy.  Bl.  527. 
8Wigmore,  op.  cit.  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  515. 

9  Tillett  v.  Ward  (1882)  10  Q.B.D.  17  ;  see  an  illuminating  discussion  of  the  law 
on  this  point  by  McCardie,  J.,  in  Gayler  and  Pope  Ltd.  v.  Davies  &  Son  Ltd.  [1924] 
2  K.B.  at  pp.  78-84. 

10  [1924]  2  K.B.  at  pp.  82-83  ;  Lord  Blackburn  had  already  expressed  the  same 
view  in  Rylands  v.  Fletcher  (1866)  L.R.  1  Ex.  at  pp.  286-287. 

II  (1877)  2  A.C.  at  p.  767. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  457 

jured  by  the  traffic  on  the  highway,  so  that  the  owner  must  bear 
his  loss  unless  he  can  show  that  some  third  person  is  in  fault — 
which  he  will  not  do  merely  by  proving  that  the  third  person  is 
the  owner  of  the  things  which  did  the  damage.  Similarly  the 
scienter  rule,  as  applied  to  dogs,  is  based  on  the  idea  that  a  man 
is  not  liable  for  damage  done  by  his  dog  unless  he  knew  his  dog 
was  fierce.1  (ii)  In  one  of  the  latest  cases  on  this  subject — 
Holmes  v.  Mather'1 — the  rule  that  a  man  is  liable  only  for  the 
proximate  consequences  of  his  acts  was  used  to  show  that,  if  the 
act  of  the  defendant  was  a  proper  act,  and  the  accident  happened 
not  by  reason  of  but  in  spite  of  it,  he  could  not  be  held  liable, 
because  the  act  which  was  the  proximate  cause  of  the  damage 
was  not  his  act.3  This  reasoning  would,  as  we  have  seen,  been 
accepted  as  valid  in  the  Middle  Ages.4  But  the  way  in  which 
this  reasoning  was  used  and  applied  was  certainly  not  mediaeval, 
and  showed  that  the  conception  of  negligence  had  made  its 
appearance  even  in  the  sphere  of  trespass. 

The  test  suggested  as  to  whether  any  given  act  was  a  trespass 
or  not,  was  whether,  firstly,  it  was  a  direct  act  of  violence,  and, 
secondly,  whether  it  was  wrongful  "  either  as  being  wilful  or  as 
being  the  result  of  negligence."  5  Let  us  consider  what  is  involved 
in  this  test.  If  the  act  which  damages  the  plaintiff  is  unlawful, 
there  is  of  course  nothing  more  to  be  said — it  is  obviously  a  tres- 
pass.6 Difficulties  begin  when  the  act  is  not  in  itself  unlawful. 
In  such  a  case  I   think   the  mediaeval  common  law  would  have 


1  See  the  cases  cited  above  456  n.  3. 

2  (1875)  L.R.  10  Ex.  261 — an  action  for  injury  to  the  person  occasioned  by  a  run- 
away horse. 

3  "  Here,  as  in  almost  all  cases,  you  must  look  at  the  immediate  act  which  did 
the  mischief,  at  what  the  driver  was  doing  before  the  mischief  happened,  and  not  to 
what  he  was  doing  next  before  what  he  was  then  doing.  If  you  looked  at  the  last  act 
but  one,  you  might  as  well  argue  that  if  the  driver  had  not  started  on  that  morning,  or 
had  not  turned  down  that  particular  street,  this  mischief  would  not  have  happened.  I 
think  the  proper  answer  is,  you  cannot  complain  of  me  unless  I  was  immediately 
doing  the  act  which  did  the  mischief  to  you.  Now  the  driver  was  not  doing  that. 
What  I  take  to  be  the  case  is  this :  he  did  not  guide  the  horses  upon  the  plaintirT ;  he 
guided  them  away  from  her,  in  another  direction  ;  but  they  ran  away  with  him,  upon 
her,  in  spite  of  his  effort  to  take  them  away  from  where  she  was,"  L.R.  10  Ex.  at 
p.  268  per  Bramwell,  B. 

4  Vol.  iii  380. 

5  "  If  the  act  that  does  an  injury  is  an  act  of  direct  force  vi  et  armis,  trespass  is 
the  proper  remedy  (if  there  is  any  remedy)  when  the  act  is  wrongful,  either  as  being 
wilful,  or  as  being  the  result  of  negligence, "per  Bramwell,  B.,  L.R.  10  Ex.  at  pp.  26S- 
269  ;  Mr.  Beven,  Negligence,  i  568,  says  that,  "  the  doing  a  lawful  act  is  not  in  itself 
sufficient  to  save  from  liability,  unless  further  it  is  done  in  circumstances  that  free  the 
doing  of  it  from  taint  of  blame  .  .  .  and  an  act  cannot  be  without  blame  and  in- 
voluntary when  there  is  free  unfettered  choice  to  act  or  refrain,  independently  of  any 
considerations  outside  the  will  of  the  person  whose  decisions  determines  the  action  "  ; 
historically  I  think  this  correctly  represents  the  earlier  law  laid  down  in  many  cases 
before  Holmes  v.  Mather,  but  not  the  law  as  stated  in  that  case. 

6  Beven,  Negligence,  i  565,  566  ;  above  449. 


458  CRIME  AND  TORT 

made  the  defendant  liable,  even  though  the  act  was  purely  ac- 
cidental, if  it  was  an  act  of  violence  committed  by  him  which  directly 
damaged  the  plaintiff.1  As  the  result  of  the  cases  of  the  seven- 
teenth eighteenth  and  nineteenth  centuries,  which  we  have  just 
been  considering,  the  defendant  escaped  liability,  if  his  act  was 
the  result  of  such  an  unavoidable  or  inevitable  necessity  that  his 
act  was  in  effect  involuntary ;  and  mitigations  also  had  been 
allowed  in  certain  cases  of  trespass  committed  by  a  defendant's 
animals.2  It  would  seem  that  the  definition  of  a  trespass  as  an  act 
of  violence  either  wilful  or  negligent,  which  was  laid  down  in 
Holmes  v.  Mather,  in  effect  carried  the  mitigation  of  a  defendant's 
liability  for  trespass  a  stage  further.  A  "wilful"  act,  I  think, 
means  an  act  done  intentionally.  The  word  "wilful"  obviously 
excludes  involuntary  acts,  and  I  think  also  lawful  acts  which  are 
voluntary,  but  which  are  done  both  without  negligence,  and  with- 
out intention  of  harming  the  plaintiff.  This  seems  clearly  to  go 
beyond  the  cases  which  we  have  just  been  considering,  because  it 
does  not  demand  that  the  act  should  have  been  the  result  of  such 
unavoidable  necessity  that  it  was  in  effect  an  involuntary  act.  In 
Holmes  v.  Mather  the  act  of  attempting  to  curb  the  runaway 
horses  was  a  lawful  voluntary  act ;  it  was  not  done  negligently ; 
and  there  was  no  intention  to  harm  the  plaintiff.  It  was  there- 
fore held  not  to  be  a  trespass  to  the  plaintiff.  The  development 
of  the  law  having  reached  this  point,  the  decision  in  the  case 
of  Stanley  v.  Powell,3  that  a  lawful  act,  which  damages  another 
accidentally,  gives  rise  to  no  cause  of  action,  was  inevitable.  In 
that  case  the  act  of  the  sportsman  in  firing  his  gun  was  a  lawful 
act ;  and  the  hitting  of  the  beater  which  followed  was  clearly  not 
intended,  and  was  found  by  the  jury  not  to  have  been  the  result 
of  negligence.4  It  did  not  therefore  comply  with  the  definition  of 
a  trespass  laid  down  in  Holmes  v.  Mather. 

Thus  negligence  came  to  be  recognized  as  the  basis  of  civil 
liability  in  a  large  and  miscellaneous  class  of  wrongs  to  person 
and  property,  which  covers  the  largest  part  of  the  sphere  of  torts. 
The  introduction  and  extension  of  this  conception  through  the 
action  on  the  case,  has  done  for  the  law  of  tort  somewhat  the 
same  service  as  the  product  of  another  action  on  the  case — the 
doctrine  of  consideration — has  done  for  the  law  of  contract.5  Just 
as  it  is  through  the  doctrine  of  consideration  that  English  law 
arrived  at  its  conception  of  a  simple  contract,  so  it  is  through  the 

1  Vol.  iii  375-377-  2  Above  455-457-  3  [1891]  1  Q.B.  86. 

4  Beven,  Negligence  i  568-570,  naturally  dissents  from  this  decision,  above  457  n.  5  ; 
his  view  is  that  the  act  of  the  defendant  was  a  voluntary  act  attended  with  possible 
danger  to  others,  that  it  was  therefore  not  without  blame,  and  consequently  was  a 
trespass. 

5  See  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  21-22. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  459 

conception  of  negligence  that  it  has  been  able  to  fix  the  standard 
of  carefulness  which  it  requires  one  man  to  observe  in  his  dealings 
with  another.  Both  conceptions  have  grown  up  under  the  shadow 
of  the  law  of  actions ;  and  both,  now  that  the  old  forms  of  actions 
are  things  of  the  past,  have  emerged  as  substantive  legal  principles. 
And  just  as  the  contract  under  seal  remains  in  our  modern  law 
as  a  survival  of  the  days  before  the  doctrine  of  consideration 
was  evolved,1  so  in  our  law  of  tort  there  are  survivals  of  ideas 
based  upon  the  mediaeval  principle  of  civil  liability.  One  illustra- 
tion is,  as  we  have  seen,  the  liability  of  the  common  carrier.*-'  A 
second  is  the  technical  meaning  of  the  defence  miscalled  con- 
tributory negligence.  Perhaps  we  may  regard  as  a  third  the  rule 
as  to  the  measure  of  damages  for  negligence  recently  laid  down 
by  the  court  of  Appeal  in  In  re  Polemis*  Of  the  history  of  the 
second  and  third  of  these  three  bodies  of  doctrine  I  must  at  this 
point  say  something. 

(i)  Contributory  negligence. 

Something  like  a  doctrine  of  contributory  negligence  was 
recognized  in  Roman  law ; 4  and  in  a  system  of  law  which 
grounded  liability  upon  negligence,  it  was  a  natural  and  a  logical 
doctrine.  But  we  have  seen  that  the  conception  of  negligence 
has  only  gradually  and  partially  been  accepted  as  a  ground  of 
civil  liability  in  the  common  law;5  and  it  was  only  at  the 
beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  when  this  development  was 
complete,  that  we  begin  to  hear  of  the  phrase  "contributor)7 
negligence."  On  the  other  hand,  the  doctrine  that,  if  the  plaintiff's 
act  was  the  proximate  cause  of  the  damage,  the  plaintiff  could 
not  recover,  was  well  established  mediaeval  doctrine,  and  wholly 
consonant  with  the  mediaeval  principles  of  civil  liability.6  But, 
when  liability  came  to  be  based,  not  merely  on  an  act  which 
caused  damage,  but  on  a  wrongful  act ;  and  when  the  largest 
number  of  acts  which  were  wrongful,  were  wrongful  because  they 
were  negligent ;  it  was  inevitable  that  the  mediaeval  doctrine 
should  somewhat  change  its  shape.  As  early  as  the  beginning 
of  the  seventeenth  century  there  was  a  dictum  to  the  effect  that, 
if  a  plaintiff  suffered  damage  by  reason  of  his  own  negligence,  he 
could  not  recover ; "  and  naturally,  as  liability  came  to  be  more 

1  Vol.  iii  419-420.  2  Above  452-453.  3  [1921]  3  K.B.  560. 

4  "  Quod  quis  ex  culpa  sua  damnum  sentit,  non  intellegitur  damnum  sentire," 
Dig.  50.  17.  203  ;  cp.  Dig.  g.  2.  11.  pr.,  cited  Beven,  Negligence  (3rd  ed.)  i  149  n.  1. 

5  Above  449-458.  •  Vol.  iii  378-379. 

7  Bayly  v.  Merrel  (1606)  Cro.  Jac.  386 — a  case  in  which  an  action  on  the  case  for 
deceit  was  held  not  to  lie,  because  the  plaintiff  could  easily  have  found  out  the  truth  if 
he  had  used  ordinary  care  ;  it  was  said  at  p.  387,  "  it  was  a  matter  which  lay  within 
his  own  view  and  conusance  ;  and  if  he  doubted  of  the  weight  thereof  he  might  have 
weighed  it ;  and  was  not  bound  to  give  credence  to  another's  speech  :  and  being  his 
own  negligence  he  is  without  remedy." 


460  CRIME  AND  TORT 

and  more  generally  grounded  on  negligence,  this  method  of  state- 
ment gained  ground.  But,  though  a  change  was  made  in  the 
method  of  statement,  the  substance  of  the  doctrine  still  retained 
a  great  deal  of  the  mediaeval  principle ;  and  it  is  this  mixture  of 
mediaeval  and  modern  principles  which  has  given  this  doctrine 
its  modern  shape. 

The  change  in  the  method  of  statement  can  be  illustrated  by 
the  form  of  the  plea  of  a  defendant  in  a  running  down  case.1  It 
runs  as  follows  : — "that  he,  the  defendant,  just  before  and  at  the 
said  time  when  he  was  driving  the  said  cart  and  horse,  in  the 
said  declaration  mentioned  ...  in  a  careful  moderate  and  proper 
manner ;  and  that,  whilst  he,  the  defendant,  was  so  driving  the 
same,  to  wit,  at  the  said  time  when,  etc.,  the  said  Sarah  [the 
plaintiff]  negligently  carelessly  and  improperly  ran  along  and 
across  the  middle  of  the  said  highway,  near  to  and  against  the 
said  horse  and  cart  of  the  said  defendant,  and  was  thereby  then 
cast  and  thrown  to  and  upon  the  ground,  and  kicked,  trampled 
upon,  and  run  over,  and  crushed,  as  in  the  said  declaration 
mentioned,  without  any  default  on  the  part  of  the  defendant. 
And  so  the  defendant  in  fact  saith  that  the  said  hurt  and  damage 
in  the  said  declaration  mentioned  were  occasioned  and  happened 
to  the  said  Sarah  by  and  through  the  mere  negligent  careless  and 
improper  conduct  of  her  the  said  Sarah,  and  not  through  the 
fault  or  improper  conduct  of  the  defendant."  It  is  clear  that  the 
plea  in  substance  appeals  to  the  mediaeval  principle  that  the 
plaintiff,  having  in  effect  been  damaged  by  her  own  act,  and  not 
by  the  act  of  the  defendant,  could  not  recover.  It  was  not  really 
a  plea  that  the  plaintiff  was  to  blame  for  negligence  which  had 
contributed  to  the  accident ;  but  a  plea  that  her  negligent  act  was 
the  direct  cause  of  the  accident.  But  the  fact  that  the  doctrine 
was  thus  stated  in  terms  of  negligence — that  emphasis  was  laid  on 
the  negligence  rather  than  on  the  act — made  a  reconsideration  of 
the  old  doctrine  necessary  from  this  new  point  of  view.  The  results 
of  that  reconsideration  were,  in  effect,  to  affirm  the  mediaeval 
principle  in  the  terms  of  the  new  phraseology — if  my  negligent 
act  is  the  direct  or  immediate  or  proximate  cause  of  the  damage, 
I  cannot  recover  ;  and  thus  to  produce  that  unfortunate  divergence 
between  the  real  contents  of  the  doctrine  and  its  name,  which, 
more  than  any  other  single  cause,  has  led  to  difficulties  in  its 
application. 

That  the  mediaeval  principle  was,  in  effect,  affirmed  in  the 
disguise  of  the  new  phraseology,  is  clear  from  the  cases  of  the 
nineteenth  and  twentieth  centuries.      In   1 809,  in  the  well-known 

1  Cotterill  v.  Starkey  (1839)  8  C.  and  P.  at  p.  692  n.  a. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  461 

case  of  Butterfield  v.  Forrester,1  the  defendant  had  negligently  put 
an  obstruction  in  a  highway  with  which  the  plaintiff  had  collided; 
but  the  plaintiff  could  not  recover  because,  "  if  he  had  used  ordinary 
care,  he  must  have  seen  the  obstruction ;  so  that  the  accident 
appeared  to  happen  entirely  from  his  own  fault"  In  1810 
Lawrence,  J.,  ruled  that  a  plaintiff  could  not  recover  from  a 
negligent  defendant,  because  "  the  immediate  and  proximate  cause  " 
of  the  damage  was  his  own  unskilfulness  as  a  driver.'2  In  1838 
Parke,  B. ,  said,  "  the  rule  is,  that,  although  there  may  have  been 
negligence  on  the  part  of  the  plaintiff,  yet,  unless  he  might,  by  the 
exercise  of  ordinary  care,  have  avoided  the  consequences  of  the 
defendant's  negligence,  he  is  entitled  to  recover  :  if  by  ordinary 
care  he  might  have  avoided  them,  he  is  the  author  of  his  own 
wrong." 3  In  1858,  in  the  case  of  Tuff  v.  Warman,  the  Exchequer 
Chamber  laid  it  down  that,  "  the  proper  question  for  the  jury  .  .  . 
is  whether  the  damage  was  occasioned  entirely  by  the  negligence 
or  improper  conduct  of  the  defendant,  or  whether  the  plaintiff 
himself  so  far  contributed  to  the  misfortune  by  his  own  negligence 
or  the  want  of  ordinary  and  common  care  and  caution,  that,  but 
for  such  negligence  or  want  of  ordinary  care  and  caution  on  his 
part,  the  misfortune  would  not  have  happened.  In  the  first  case 
the  plaintiff  would  be  entitled  to  recover,  in  the  latter  not ;  as,  but 
for  his  own  fault,  the  misfortune  would  not  have  happened."  4  In 
19 16  the  manner  in  which  the  rule  was  laid  down  in  Tuff  v. 
Warman,  was  expressly  approved  by  Lord  Sumner.5 

It  would  seem  to  follow  that  the  question  of  negligence  is  only 
material  in  order  to  show  that  acts  done  by  the  plaintiff  and 
defendant  are  wrongful.  The  substance  of  the  defence  called 
"contributory  negligence  "  is  not  the  fact  that  the  plaintiff  has 
been  negligent ;  but  that  his  negligent  act  is  the  direct  cause  of  the 
accident  In  other  words,  as  in  the  Middle  Ages,  the  defendant, 
who  succeeds  on  this  plea,  escapes  because  it  was  not  his  wrongful 
act,  but  the  wrongful  act  of  the  plaintiff,  which  was  the  direct  cause 
of  the  accident  It  follows  that,  as  the  plaintiff  must  in  all  cases 
prove  that  it  was  the  negligent  act  of  the  defendant  which  caused 
the  damage  of  which  he  is  complaining,  if  his  negligence  had  as 
great  a  share  in  causing  the  damage  as  that  of  the  defendant — if, 
for  instance,  the  negligent  acts  of  the  plaintiff  and  defendant  were 
contemporaneous,  he  cannot  recover.6     In  fact  the  decision  in  the 

1 11  East  60  ;  approved  by  Esher  M.R.  in  The  Bernina  (1887)  12  P.D.  at  p.  70. 

2  Flower  v.  Adam  2  Taunt.  314,  at  p.  317. 

3  Bridge  v.  Grand  Junction  Railwav  Co.  3  M.  and  W.  at  p.  248. 
1 5  C.B.  N.S.  at  p.  585. 

3  British  Columbia  Electric  Railway  Co.  v.  Loach  [1916]  1  A.C.  at  pp.  724-725. 
6  The  Bernina  (1887)  12  P.D.  at  p.  89  per  Lindley,  L.J.     It  should  be  noted  that, 
though  it  is  logically  correct  to  say  that  such  a  case  of  contemporaneous  negligence  is  a 


462  CRIME  AND  TORT 

case  of  British  Columbia  Electric  Co.  v.  Loach}  that  the  defendant's 
previous  and  continuing  negligence,  which  prevented  him  from 
having  the  last  chance  of  escape,  was  a  sufficient  answer  to  negli- 
gence on  the  part  of  the  plaintiff,  which  was  in  fact  the  direct  cause 
of  the  accident,  is  the  first  case  in  which  a  plaintiff,  whose  negligence 
was  in  fact  the  direct  cause  of  the  accident,  was  allowed  to  recover. 
So  that,  paradoxical  though  it  may  seem,  it  might  be  contended  that 
this  was  the  first  case  in  which  a  consideration  of  the  comparative 
negligences  of  the  plaintiff  and  defendant  was  a  real  element  in 
the  defence.  As  I  said  in  an  earlier  volume,2  the  doctrine  in  the 
form  in  which  it  exists  in  our  modern  common  law  is  anomalous. 
It  is  anomalous,  because  it  represents  an  attempt  to  piece  together 
two  incompatible  theories  of  civil  liability — the  mediaeval  theory 
that  liability  is  based  on  an  act  which  causes  damage,  and  the 
modern  theory  that  liability  is,  as  a  general  rule,  based  upon  some 
moral  fault,  either  of  the  negligent  or  of  the  intentional  variety.3 

(ii)   The  measure  of  damages  for  negligence. 

This  is  a  very  modern  question ;  and  it  was  only  definitely 
settled  (as  far  as  the  court  of  Appeal  can  settle  it)  in  1921  by  the 
case  of  In  re  PolemisA  Down  to  the  decision  of  this  case  it  was  a 
very  moot  point  whether  the  measure  of  damages  for  negligence 
was  to  be  determined  by  the  same  test  as  that  which  determined 
the  existence  of  negligence — the  test,  that  is,  of  an  enquiry  whether 
the  damage  caused  was  such  that  a  reasonable  person  might  have 
anticipated  it ; 5  or  whether,  where  negligence  had  been  proved, 
the  wrongdoer  was  liable  for  all  the  damage  directly  flowing  from 
his  negligence,  whether  he  could  have  anticipated  it  or  not.     The 


case  of  contributory  negligence,  because  the  negligence  of  both  parties  contributed  to  the 
accident,  the  defence  of  contributory  negligence  is  only  available  to  a  defendant  who  can 
prove  that  the  plaintiff's  negligence  was  subsequent  to  his  own  ;  some  confusion  is 
sometimes  caused  by  neglecting  to  distinguish  between  cases  where  there  has  been 
contributory  negligence,  and  cases  where  the  defence  of  contributory  negligence  is  avail- 
able— e.g.  in  Davies  v.  Mann  (1842)  10  M.  and  W.  546  there  was  contributory  negli- 
gence, but  the  defence  of  contributorynegligence  was  not  available,  because  the  defendant's 
negligence  was  subsequent  to  the  plaintiff's,  and  the  direct  cause  of  the  accident.  In 
other  words,  when  we  are  speaking  of  the  defence  of  contributory  negligence,  we  are 
not  using  the  words  "  contributory  negligence  "  in  the  ordinary  sense,  but  in  a  very 
technical  sense. 

1  [1916]  1  A.C.  719.  3  Vol.  iii  378-379. 

3  Lindley,  L.J.,  in  The  Bernina  (1887)  12  P.D.  at  p.  89,  after  dealing  with  the  case 
of  contemporaneous  negligence,  above  461,  and  after  stating  that  the  rule  in  that  case  is 
the  logical  result  of  the  common  law  principles,  says,  "  why  in  such  a  case  the  damages 
should  not  be  apportioned  I  do  not  profess  to  understand"  ;  it  is  submitted  that  the 
historical  evolution  of  the  rule  supplies  the  explanation ;  it  is  in  fact  the  direct  and 
logical  consequence  of  the  mediaeval  principle. 

4  [1921]  3  K.B.  560. 

s  The  authorities  in  favour  of  this  view  are  very  well  summarised  in  Mr.  R.  A. 
Wright's  unsuccessful  argument  for  the  appellants  in  In  re  Polemis  [1921]  3  K.B.  at 
pp.  564-566  ;  and  in  Sir  F.  Pollock's  article  in  L.Q.R.  xxxviii  165. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  463 

case  of  In  re  Poletnis  decides,  in  accordance  with  the  preponderance 
of  recent  opinion,1  that  the  latter  alternative  is  correct. 

Upon  purely  logical  grounds  the  justice  of  this  conclusion  is 
perhaps  open  to  question.  If  we  are  basing  liability  upon  an  act 
which  causes  damage,  without  any  reference  to  negligence,  the  rule 
is  logical  enough.  But  if  we  are  basing  liability  upon  a  negligent 
act,  and  if  negligence  consists  in  a  failure  to  foresee  results  which 
ought  reasonably  to  have  been  foreseen,  it  would  seem  that  the 
negligent  person  ought  only  to  be  made  liable  to  the  extent  to 
which  he  ought  to  have  foreseen  those  results.  In  the  law  of 
contract  it  is  admitted  that  the  agreement  of  the  parties  governs 
the  situation,  so  that  only  those  damages  can  be  recovered,  ' '  which 
may  fairly  and  reasonably  be  considered  either  arising  naturally, 
i.e.  according  to  the  usual  course  of  things,  from  such  breach  of 
contract  itself,  or  such  as  may  reasonably  be  supposed  to  have  been 
in  the  contemplation  of  both  parties,  at  the  time  they  made  the 
contract,  as  the  probable  result  of  the  breach  of  it."  -  If  the  basis 
of  the  liability  in  contract — the  agreement  and  its  breach — is 
allowed  to  affect  the  measure  of  damages  for  breach  of  contract,  it 
is  a  little  difficult  to  see  why  the  basis  of  the  liability  for  negligence 
— the  failure  to  foresee  acts  which  ought  reasonably  to  have  been 
foreseen — is  not  allowed  to  affect  the  measure  of  liability  for 
negligent  acts. 

But,  upon  historical  grounds,  the  conclusion  arrived  at  in  the 
case  of  In  re  Poletnis  is  interesting  for  three  reasons :  firstly,  be- 
cause it  shows  the  continuous  bias  of  the  courts  in  favour  of  making 
a  defendant  liable  for  all  the  consequences  of  a  wrongful  act  flowing 
directly  therefrom,  without  reference  to  his  mental  state.3  From 
this  point  of  view  it  is  comparable  to  the  manner  in  which  the 
courts  have  treated  the  defence  of  contributory  negligence  ;  for,  as 
in  that  case,  the  go-by  is  given  to  any  consideration  of  the  respec- 
tive seriousness  of  the  negligence  of  the  two  parties,  and  the  court 
merely  looks  to  see  to  whose  act  of  negligence  the  damage  is 
directly  attributable;  4  so  in  considering  the  measure  of  damages 
for  a  negligent  act,  the  court  gives  the  go-by  to  the  basis  upon 
which  the  liability  is  founded,  by  refusing  to  consider  what  damage 
might  reasonably  be  expected  to  result  from  the  negligence,  and 
merely  looks  to  see  what  damage  has  directly  resulted.  It  seems 
to  me  that,  just  as  Lindley,  L.J.,  doubted  the  justice  of  the  rule 
governing  the  defence  of  contributory  negligence,5  so  there  is  some 
point  in  the  doubt  of  Vaughan-Williams,  L.J.,  as  to  the  justice  of 

1  See  Beven,  Negligence  (3rd  ed.)  i  105-108 ;  Weld-BIundell  v.  Stephens  [1920] 
A.C.  at  pp.  983-984  per  Lord  Sumner. 

2  Hadley  v.  Baxendale  (1854)  9  Ex.  at  p.  354. 

3  Vol.  iii  375-377  ;  above  449-450.  4  Above  461-462. 
'Above  462  n.  3. 


464  CRIME  AND  TORT 

the  rule  governing  the  measure  of  damages  for  a  negligent  act.1 
In  both  cases  the  logical  consequences  of  taking  negligence  as  a 
basis  of  liability  seem  to  be  disregarded.  Secondly,  this  rule  is 
historically  interesting  because  it  shows  the  continued  adherence 
to  the  very  primitive  principle  laid  down  by  Bacon2  and  Hale,3 
that,  in  adjudicating  upon  questions  of  civil  liability,  the  law  looks, 
not  at  the  extent  of  the  demerits  of  the  wrongdoer,  but  at  the 
damage  of  the  party  injured.  This  is,  in  fact,  the  ground  upon 
which  the  rule  is  based  by  Beven  ; 4  and  it  is,  it  seems  to  me,  the 
only  logical  ground  upon  which  it  can  be  based.  Thirdly,  the 
rule  makes  it  very  much  easier  to  estimate  the  measure  of  damages  ; 
for  it  makes  it  unnecessary  to  separate  the  items  of  damage  fairly 
attributable  to  the  defendant's  negligence,  from  those  not  fairly 
attributable.  In  thus  laying  down  a  rule  which  makes  for  sim- 
plicity and  the  saving  of  labour,  at  the  cost  of  neglecting  other 
considerations  which  might  lead  to  a  different  solution,  the  judges 
of  this  century  have  followed  the  example  of  their  predecessors  in 
other  periods  of  the  history  of  the  common  law.5 

It  follows  that  both  the  manner  in  which  courts  have  treated 
the  defence  of  contributory  negligence,  and  the  manner  in  which 
they  have  treated  the  measure  of  damages  for  negligence,  illus- 
trate the  imperfect  way  in  which  the  conception  of  negligence 
has,  owing  to  its  comparatively  recent  and  gradual  introduction 
into  the  common  law,  been  reconciled  with  earlier  conceptions  of 
liability.  In  this,  as  in  other  branches  of  the  common  law  at 
different  periods — in  the  mediaeval  law,  for  instance,  as  to  convey- 
ancing,6 as  to  incorporeal  things,"  and  as  to  the  corporation  sole8 
— the  survival  of  earlier  ideas  has  exercised  a  distorting  effect 
upon  later  legal  developments.  We  shall  now  see  that  there  are 
certain  other  cases  in  which  earlier  principles  of  liability  have  in 
substance  survived,  but  for  reasons  very  different  from  those  upon 
which  they  were  originally  based. 

(2)  The  place  of  the  mediaeval  principle  of  liability  in  modern 
law. 

1  "  It  seems  to  me  difficult  to  be  satisfied  with  a  rule  which  would  make  the 
measure  of  damages,  where  the  wrongful  act  is  absolutely  the  same  in  two  cases, 
differ  absolutely  according  to  the  loss  which  has  been  sustained  by  the  person  who  is 
injured  by  the  collision — though  the  wrongful  act  of  the  wrongdoer  is  identical  in  both 
cases.     Still  the  rule  seems  now  to  be  fully  adopted,"  The  Racine  [1906]  P.  at  p.  277. 

2  Cited  vol.  iii  375.  3  Cited  ibid  376. 

4  "  The  test  is  not  the  mala  mens  of  the  actor,  but  the  damnum  et  injuria  to  the 
sufferer,"  Negligence  i  108  ;  as  I  have  already  pointed  out,  vol.  ii  51-52,  vol.  iii 
371-375,  we  can  trace  this  principle  back  to  the  Anglo-Saxon  period. 

5  We  can  see  parallels  in  the  way  the  mediasval  common  law  treated  the  husband's 
right  to  curtesy,  vol.  iii  187  ;  the  married  woman's  proprietary  capacity,  ibid  524  ;  and 
the  jury,  vol.  i  318. 

8  Vol.  iii  224.  7  Ibid  97-101.  8  Ibid  481-482. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  465 

In  our  modern  law  there  are  two  main  classes  of  cases  in 
which  the  mediaeval  principle  of  liability  is  still  applied.  The 
first  is  the  case  where  one  man  has  done  an  act  which  infringes 
his  neighbour's  possession  of,  or  right  to  possess,  land  or  chattels. 
The  second  is  the  class  of  cases  which,  in  our  modern  law,  fall 
under  the  rule  in  Fletcher  v.  Ry lands} 

(i)  We  have  seen  that,  in  certain  cases,  acts  which  infringe 
another's  possession  of  land  or  goods  were  and  are  justifiable.  - 
But,  apart  from  these  exceptions,  any  interference  with  possession 
or  the  right  to  possess  is  an  act  which  will  entitle  the  injured 
part)'  to  bring  an  action  in  tort.  The  fact  that  the  act  is  done 
accidentally,  or  in  good  faith,  or  under  a  justifiable  error,  is  no 
defence.3  At  a  time  when  civil  liability  for  all  wrongs,  both  to 
person  and  property,  was  based  on  this  principle,  the  severity  of 
the  law  would  hardly  seem  to  call  for  explanation.  But  we  have 
seen  that,  in  the  fifteenth  century,  some  mitigation  of  this  strict 
liability  was  hinted  at  in  the  cases  where  the  damage  was  inevit- 
able or  caused  by  "  the  act  of  God." 4  It  is  not  surprising,  there- 
fore, that  the  tendency  to  mitigate  these  rules  should  have  been 
applied  both  to  injuries  to  the  person  and  to  injuries  to  property.5 
Thus  we  have  seen  that  it  was  said  in  Edward  IV.'s  reign  that,  if 
a  drover  was  driving  cattle  along  a  highway,  and  by  chance  they 
got  a  mouthful  of  corn,  no  action  lay ;  and  that  by  custom  the 
same  rule  applied  if,  in  ploughing,  the  plough  turned  upon 
another's  land.6  We  have  seen,  too,  that  in  Henry  VI I. 's  reign 
Rede,  J.,  had  said  that  if  two  men's  cattle  were  together  in  a 
field,  one  might  drive  the  other's  cattle  till  he  could  get  them  into  a 
strait  place  where  they  could  be  severed ; "  and  in  the  same  case 
the  same  judge  said  that,  where  the  executors  of  a  deceased  man 
take  the  goods  of  another  together  with  the  goods  of  the  testator, 
they  are  not  liable  to  be  sued  in  trespass,  because  they  had  no 
means  of  knowing  which  were  the  goods  of  the  deceased,  and 
which  were  the  goods  of  a  stranger.8  In  one  or  two  later  cases, 
also,  we  see  traces  of  the  same  tendency.  We  have  seen  that,  in 
the  absence  of  a  scienter,  a  man  is  not  liable  for  damage  done  by 
his  dog,9  or,  it  would  seem,  for  any  of  his  other  animals  man- 
suetae  naturae ; lu  and  though,  as  we  shall  see,  a  man  is  absolutely 
liable  if  cattle  break  out  of  his  close  and  trespass  on  that  of 

1  (1866)  L.R.  1  Ex.  265  ;  (1868)  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  330. 

*  Vol.  iii  377-378.  3  Ibid  382  ;  below  466-467.  *  Vol.  iii  380-382. 

5  See  Wigmore,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  508. 

6  Y.B.  22  Ed.  IV.  Pasch.  pi.  24,  cited  vol.  iii  380-381. 

'  Y.B.  22  Hy.  VII.  Trin.  pi.  5  (p.  28),  cited  vol.  iii  381. 

8  "  On  ne  peut  prima  facie  avoir  parfait  conusance  que  des  biens  sont  al  testator, 
et  que  a  l'estranger." 

•  Above  456,  457.  w  Manton  v.  Brocklebank  [1923]  2  K.B.  212. 

VOL.  VIIL— 30 


466  CRIME  AND  TORT 

another,1  he  is  not  absolutely  liable  for  the  trespasses  of  his  cattle 
while  being  driven  along  the  highway.2  In  the  case  of  Beckwith 
v.  S/zordike3  the  court  seems  to  have  thought  that  an  involuntary 
and  accidental  entry  on  the  plaintiff's  close  was  no  trespass ;  and 
in  the  case  of  Davis  v.  Saunders^  damage  done  to  the  plaintiff's 
ship  without  the  negligence  of  the  defendant,  and  while  he  was 
doing  a  lawful  act,  was  held  to  give  no  cause  of  action. 

It  is  clear,  therefore,  that  there  was  a  tendency  to  apply  to 
liability  for  damage  to  property  the  same  sort  of  mitigation  as 
was  applied  to  damage  to  the  person.  But  this  tendency  has  not 
been  allowed  to  develop  to  anything  like  the  same  extent  as  in 
the  parallel  case  of  damage  to  the  person.  It  would  not  indeed 
be  true  to  say  that  it  has  had  no  effect  whatever.5  It  would  seem 
that  in  cases  like  Davis  v.  Saunders,  where  damage  has  been 
caused  by  vis  major  in  the  doing  of  a  lawful  act,  there  is 
no  trespass  and  therefore  no  liability ;  and  the  strict  rule  of 
liability  has  certainly  been  modified,  both  in  the  case  of  dogs  and 
other  animals  manusuetae  naturae  and  not  known  to  be  savage, 
and  in  the  case  of  damage  accidentally  caused  by  cattle  while 
being  driven  along  the  highway.6  Moreover,  in  Manton  v. 
Brocklebank  Lord  Justice  Atkin  said7  that  "if  Holmes  v.  Mather* 
be  correctly  decided  trespass  to  goods  must  be  the  result  of  an 
act  either  wilful  or  negligent."  This  in  effect  asserts  that 
liability  for  trespass  to  the  person  and  to  property  rest  upon 
the  same  principles.  And  no  doubt  there  is  a  sense  in  which 
this  is  true.  If,  in  Stanley  v.  Powell?  the  shot,  instead  of  hitting 
the  beater,  had  hit  a  plate  belonging  to  the  host  which  had  just 
been  unpacked  from  a  lunch  basket,  it  is  obvious  that  the  plaintiff 
could  not  have  been  made  liable.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  quite 
clear  that  for  any  asportation  or  conversion  of  a  chattel,  or  for 
any  act  which  amounts  to  the  breaking  of  the  plaintiffs  close, 
a  man  is  absolutely  liable ;  and  that  many  of  the  modifications  of 
the  strict  rule,  suggested  in  some  of  the  earlier  cases,10  are  not 
accepted  as  law  at  the  present  day.  It  is  clear  that  if  one  turns 
his  plough,  or  accidentally  enters  upon  another's  land;11  or,  it 
would   seem,  if  executors  take  the  goods  of  another  under  the 

I  Below  470-471.  2  Above  456-457. 

3  (1767)  4  Burr,  at  p.  2093  ;  above  456. 

4  (1770)  2  Chitty  (K.B.)  639,    cited  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  146. 

5  This  seems  to  be  the  view  of  Wigmore,  op.  cit.,  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  508. 
e  Above  456-457,  465.  7  [1923]  2  K.B.  at  p.  229. 

8  (1875)  L.R.  10  Ex.  261.  8[i8gi]  1  Q.B.  86. 

10  Above  465. 

II  Basely  v.  Clarkson  (1681)  3  Lev.  37  ;  "  by  the  laws  of  England  every  invasion 
of  private  property,  be  it  never  so  minute,  is  a  trespass.  No  man  can  set  his  foot  upon 
my  ground  without  my  licence,  but  he  is  liable  to  an  action,  though  the  damage  be 
nothing,"  Entick  v.  Carrington  (1765)  19  S.T.  at  p.  1066  per  Lord  Camden,  C.J. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  467 

bona  fide  and  justifiable  belief  that  they  belong  to  the  deceased  ; ' 
or  if  one  converts  another's  goods,  though  he  has  no  knowledge 
or  means  of  knowledge  to  displace  his  bona  fide  and  justifiable 
belief  that  they  are  his  own2 — all  can  be  made  liable  in  an  action 
of  trespass  or  conversion.  How  then  can  we  explain  this  apparent 
contradiction  that,  though  in  theory  liability  for  trespass  to  the 
person  and  to  property  rests  upon  the  same  principles,  yet  in 
practice  liability  for  trespass  to  property  is  more  severe,  and,  in 
many  cases,  does  not  differ  very  materially  from  the  mediaeval 
principle? 

The  explanation  is,  I  think,  this :  even  the  smallest  inter- 
ference with  possession  or  the  right  to  possess  is  an  unlawful  act, 
and,  because  it  is  an  unlawful  act,3  it  gives  rise  to  an  action  for 
trespass  or  conversion.  It  is  only  if  the  act  involves  no  asporta- 
tion or  conversion  in  the  case  of  a  chattel,  or  no  breaking  of  the 
plaintiff's  close  in  the  case  of  land,  that  it  will  only  be  tortious  if  it 
is  either  wilful 4  or  negligent ;  and  such  cases  must  obviously  be 
rare,  i  f  we  go  further,  and  ask  why  the  law  has  always  adhered 
rigidly  to  the  view  that  any  such  interference  is  an  unlawful  act, 
we  shall,  as  Sir  F.  Pollock  has  pointed  out,5  find  the  reason  in  the 
manner  in  which,  owing  to  procedural  conveniences,  delictual 
remedies  came  to  be  used  for  the  protection  of  ownership  and 
possession.  Ejectment,6  trespass  quare  clausum  fregit,  trespass  de 
bonis  asportatis,  and  conversion,"  were  all  essentially  delictual 
remedies.  But  we  have  seen  that  they  have  come  to  be  the 
regular  actions,  in  which  not  only  torts  to  possession  and  owner- 
ship can  be  redressed,  but  also  rights  to  possession  and  ownership 
can  be  asserted.  Thus  "the  distinction  between  proceedings 
taken  on  a  disputed  claim  of  right,  and  those  taken  for  the  redress 
of  injuries,  where  the  right  was  assumed  not  to  be  in  dispute, 
became  quite  obliterated."8  And,  it  should  be  remembered  that 
the  common  law  did  not  draw  any  hard  and  fast  line  between 
possession  and  ownership.  A  possessor  is  treated  as  owner  as 
against  all  the  world  save  as  against  the  man  with  the  better  right. 9 
But  rights  of  ownership  have  come  to  be  regarded  as  absolute  rights 
as  against  all  the  world.10  Therefore  any  infringement  of  these 
rights  must  be  accounted  an  unlawful  act  which  will  give  rise 
to  an  action  for  damages,  whatever  may  be  the  cause  for  that 

1  They  might  of  course  be  entitled  to  an  indemnity  as  against  the  estate  if  they 
had  acted  honestly  and  reasonably,  see  Re  Raybould  [1900]  1  Ch.  199. 

2  Hollins  v.  Fowler  (1874)  L.R.  7  H.  of  L.  757.  s  Above  449. 
*  See  above  458  for  the  sense  in  which  this  term  is  used. 

5  Torts  (12th  ed.)  11-14.  8  Vol.  vii  7,  57. 

7  Vol.  vii  402-440.  8  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  13. 

9  Vol.  iii  91-95,  352353  I  vol.  vii  59-60,  449. 

10  Vol.  vii  62-68,  426-430. 


468  CRIME  AND  TORT 

infringement,  and  whether  or  not  the  person  who  has  infringed 
them  is  morally  blameworthy.1  As  he  is  thus  in  effect  absolutely 
liable  for  any  act  which  has  the  result  of  infringing  these  rights, 
his  liability  is  in  all  essentials  governed  by  the  same  principles  as 
governed  all  liability  for  tort  in  the  mediaeval  common  law.'*' 

(ii)  The  principle  of  the  class  of  cases  which  fall  under  the 
rule  in  Fletcher  v.  Rylands 3  is  thus  stated  by  Sir  F.  Pollock : 4 
"The  law  takes  notice  that  certain  things  are  a  source  of  extra- 
ordinary risk,  and  a  man  who  exposes  his  neighbour  to  such 
risk  is  held  answerable  to  his  neighbours  as  an  insurer  against 
consequent  mischief."  In  effect  his  liability  is  essentially  the 
same  as  that  imposed  by  the  mediaeval  common  law ;  for,  though 
absence  of  negligence  will  not  excuse  him,  vis  major,5  or  the  fact 
that  the  damage  is  caused,  not  by  his  own  act,  but  by  the  act  of 
the  plaintiff  or  of  a  third  person  with  whom  he  is  in  no  way 
connected,0  is  a  good  defence.  His  acts  are  at  his  peril ;  but  for 
damage  which  results,  not  from  his  act,  but  from  the  act  of  God 
or  of  the  plaintiff  or  of  a  third  person,  he  is  not  liable.7 

The  decision  in  this  case  is  the  starting  point  of  the  modern 
law  as  to  the  liability  of  one  who  engages  on  a  dangerous  under- 
taking, because  it  stated  broadly  and  clearly  the  nature  of  the 
liability  imposed,  and  the  cases  to  which  it  applies.  It  is  clear 
that  the  rule  could  not  have  been  laid  down  in  this  way  in  the 
mediaeval  common  law,  because  the  principle  of  civil  liability  set 
out  in  that  case  was  applied,  not  merely  to  dangerous  acts  which 
caused  damage,  but  to  all  acts,  if  they  came  within  some  one  of 
the  forms  of  action  recognized  by  the  law — a  truth  which  was,  as 
we  have  seen,  recognized  by  Lord  Cranworth  in  his  judgment  in 
Fletcher  v.  Rylands}  This  rule  could  only  emerge  as  a  distinct 
and  exceptional  rule  when  the  mediaeval  principle  of  civil  liability 
had  ceased  to  be  the  general  rule.  It  follows,  therefore,  that,  till 
well  on  in  the  nineteenth  century,  the  time  was  hardly  ripe  for  its 
enunciation.  But  though,  as  expressed  in  Fletcher  v.  Rylands,  it 
is  a  modern  rule,  it  has  at  least  two  ancient  roots.  In  the  first 
place,  it  gives  effect  to  the  idea,  expressed  in  different  ways  at 
different  periods,  that  the  doing  of  dangerous  things  should  give 

1  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  11-12.  3  Vol.  iii  375-377. 

;i  (1866)  L.R.  1  Ex.  265 ;  (1868)  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  330. 

4  Torts  (12th  ed.)  490. 

5  Nichols  v.  Marsland  (1875-1876)  L.R.  10  Ex.  255 ;  2  Ex.  Div.  1. 

8  Box  v.  Jubb  (1879)  4  Ex.  Div.  76 ;  he  would  of  course  be  liable  for  the  act  of 
his  servant,  acting  within  the  scope  of  his  employment,  under  the  modern  doctrine  of 
employers'  liability,  and  also  for  the  acts  of  an  independent  contractor,  see  L.Q.R.  xxv 
320. 

7  For  the  similarity  of  these  rules  to  the  general  rules  as  to  civil  liability  in  the 
Middle  Ages  see  vol.  iii  378,  380. 

8  (1868)  L.R.  3  H.  of  L.  at  p.  341 ;  above  454,  455. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  469 

rise  to  a  stricter  liability.  In  the  second  place,  it  is  influenced  by 
the  survival  of  the  mediaeval  rules  as  to  damage  to  property 
which  I  have  just  described.1 

(a)  The  principle  that  the  doing  of  obviously  dangerous  acts 
should  impose  a  stricter  liability  was  recognized  in  the  Middle 
Ages.  One  of  these  cases  was  the  liability  imposed  on  house- 
holders to  keep  their  fires  from  causing  damage.  The  form  which 
this  stricter  liability  took  was  not  the  form  taken  by  the  rule  in 
Ry lands  v.  Fletcher,  for  that  rule  was  then  the  general  rule  of 
civil  liability.  It  took  the  form  of  a  rule  that  a  householder 
was  liable  for  damage  caused  by  his  fire,  even  though  that 
damage  was  occasioned  not  by  his  own  act,  but  by  the  act  of  his 
servants  or  guests.*2  This  strict  rule  of  liability  for  damage  caused 
by  fire  was  recognized  in  1698  in  the  case  of  Tuberville  v.  Stamp  ; 3 
but  it  was  altered  by  the  Legislature  in  1707;4  and  liability  for 
the  acts  of  one's  servants,  whether  in  the  course  of  doing  a 
dangerous  act  or  not,  is  now  governed  by  the  modern  principle  of 
employers'  liability.5  But  this  mediaeval  rule  is  clearly  one 
illustration  of  the  recognition  of  the  first  of  the  ideas  on  which 
the  rule  in  Rvlands  v.  Fletclier  is  based. 

Another  illustration  is  to  be  found  in  the  development  of  the 
law  as  to  the  keeping  of  animals.  We  have  seen  that  liability  for 
the  damage  caused  by  ordinarily  tame  animals  was  modified  by 
the  growth  of  the  scienter  rule ; 6  but,  as  Hale  points  out,  the  old 
strict  liability  remained  if  scienter  could  be  proved,  or  if  the 
animal  was  naturally  wild."  In  1700,  in  the  case  of  Mason  v. 
Keeling,  Holt,  C.J.,  stated  the  law  in  the  same  way  as  Hale  had 
stated  it  He  said,  "if  it  had  been  said  that  the  defendant  knew 
the  dog  to  be  ferox,  I  should  think  it  enough.  The  difference  is 
between  things  in  which  the  party  has  a  valuable  property,  for  he 
shall  answer  for  all  damages  done  by  them  ;  but  of  things  in  which 
he  has  no  valuable  property,  if  they  are  such  as  are  naturally 

1  Above  467-468. 

3  Vol.  iii  385  ;  Wigmore,  op.  tit.,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  511-512. 

a  1  Salk.  13  ;  the  allegation  of  negligence,  which  there  appears,  was  clearly  un- 
necessary, see  Wigmore,  loc.  cit.,  and  the  statutes  cited  in  the  next  note ;  as  we  have 
seen,  we  should  not  attach  much  weight  to  the  adverbs  used  in  writs  or  declarations, 
vol.  iii  452  n.  9  ;  it  was  because  Blackstone  paid  too  much  attention  to  them  that  he 
erroneously  stated,  Comm.  iii  211,  that  the  liability  for  cattle  trespass,  below  470-471, 
and  for  damage  done  by  fire,  ibid  i  419,  was  for  negligently  keeping  one's  cattle  or 
fire;  cp.  Lord  Lyndhurst's  criticism  in  Viscount  Canterbury  v.  the  Queen  (1842) 
4  S.T.N  .S.  at  pp.  774-775- 

*6  Anne  c.  31  §  6,  made  perpetual  by  10  Anne  c.  14  §  1. 

5  Below  472  seqq. 

s  Above  456-457. 

7 "  In  case  of  such  a  wild  beast,  or  in  case  of  a  bull  or  cow,  that  doth 
damage,  when  the  owner  knows  of  it,  he  must  at  his  peril  keep  him  up  safe  from  doing 
hurt,  for  tho'  he  uses  his  diligence  to  keep  him  up,  if  he  escape  and  do  harm,  the  owner 
is  liable  to  answer  damages,''  P.C.  i  430. 


470  CRIME  AND  TORT 

mischievous  in  their  kind,  he  shall  answer  for  the  hurt  done  by  them 
without  any  notice  ;  but  if  they  are  of  a  tame  nature  there  must  be 
notice  of  the  ill  quality." x  Holt,  C.  J.,  thus  lays  down  the  modern 
rule  as  to  liability  for  the  acts  of  dangerous  animals  clearly  enough  ; 
but  the  distinction  which  he  drew,  based  on  the  question  whether 
or  not  the  defendant  had  a  valuable  property  in  the  animal,  calls 
for  an  explanation.  It  was  said  as  late  as  1676  that,  if  a  savage 
animal  escaped,  the  former  owner  ceased  to  be  liable  for  any 
damage  afterwards  done  by  the  animal.2  This  was  based  on  the 
view  that  such  an  animal  by  its  escape  became  a  res  nullius,  so 
that  his  former  owner,  because  he  had  ceased  to  be  the  owner, 
ceased  to  be  liable  for  its  acts.3  This  rule  has  ceased  to  be  law 
in  the  form  in  which  it  was  stated  in  1676,4  though  possibly  it 
still  influences  the  law  as  to  the  trespass  of  such  animals  on  to 
another's  land.5  Holt  probably  had  this  rule  in  his  mind  ;6  but 
what  he  was  chiefly  thinking  of  was  the  very  much  stricter  liability 
which  the  law  then  imposed,  and  still  imposes,  on  a  person  whose 
cattle  trespass  on  another's  property.  It  is  true  that  his  statement 
of  the  law  was  not  accurate  ; 7  for,  as  we  have  seen,  it  was  not  true 
that  the  owner  of  cattle  was  bound  to  answer  for  all  damage 
done  by  them.8  But  he  was  and  is  absolutely  liable  if  they  escape 
from  his  land,  and  trespass  on  to  another's  land.  This  liability  is 
another  root  of  the  rule  in  Ry lands  v.  Fletcher :  but  its  considera- 
tion falls  more  properly  under  the  following  head. 

(b)  The  absolute  liability  of  the  owner  of  cattle  if  they  escape 
from  his  land,  and  trespass  on  to  the  land  of  his  neighbour,  has 
ancient  roots.  It  may  have  originated  in  the  primitive  idea  that 
animals  which  had  done  damage  were  in  some  way  guilty,  and 
that  the  owner  must  be  made  liable  as  a  means  "of  getting  at 
the  animal  which  was  the  immediate  cause  of  offence."  9  But, 
certainly  by  the  fifteenth  century,  these  primitive  ideas  had  dis- 
appeared. The  rule  that  the  owner  of  trespassing  cattle  was 
liable  had  become  a  fixed  rule  of  law,  as  to  the  reasonableness  of 
which  the  author  of  the  Doctor  and  Student  had  doubts ; 10  but 
there  can  be  no  doubt  that  it  could  be  and  was  explained  on 

1  12  Mod.  at  p.  335.  2  Mitchil  v.  Alestree  1  Vent.  395  per  Twisden,  J. 

3  Vol.  vii  492,  493  ;  see  Holmes,  Common  Law  22,  for  the  view  that  this  dictum 
was  influenced,  perhaps  unconsciously,  by  the  notion  that  the  ground  of  liability  was 
noxal,  i.e.  based  on  the  ownership  of  a  guilty  thing. 

4  May  v.  Burdett  (1846)  9  Q.B.  at  p.  113. 

'Thus  in  Cox  v.  Burbidge  (1863)  13  C.B.  N.S.  at  p.  438  Williams,  J.,  says,  "if 
I  am  the  owner  of  an  animal  in  which  by  law  the  right  of  property  can  exist,  I  am 
bound  to  take  care  that  it  does  not  stray  into  the  land  of  my  neighbour." 

6  Ibid  at  p.  440  per  Willes,  J. 

7  Ibid  at  pp.  440-441  per  Willes,  J. ;  as  he  says,  Holt's  dictum  "  exhausts  itself  on 
the  liability  of  the  owners  of  horses  and  oxen  for  trespasses  committed  by  them  on 
land." 

8  Above  456,  465-466.  9  Holmes,  Common  Law  10. 
10  Bk.  1  c.  9,  cited  Wigmore,  op.  cit.,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  514  n.  4. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  471 

somewhat  the  same  grounds  as  the  rule  which  made  anyone  liable 
who  infringed  another's  possession  or  right  to  possession.1  As  we 
have  seen,  the  right  to  a  free  enjoyment  of  possession  is  as  much 
an  incident  of  ownership  as  the  right  to  its  undisturbed  possession. 
In  the  sphere  of  the  real  actions  the  former  right  was  protected 
by  the  assize  of  nuisance,  as  the  latter  right  was  protected  by 
the  assize  of  novel  disseisin.2  Liability  for  trespass  by  cattle 
was  put  on  this  proprietary  ground  in  1480  ;3  and  clearly,  if  this 
liability  is  regarded  in  this  way,  it  is  in  effect  a  liability  for 
nuisance.  The  nature  of  this  liability  was,  as  we  have  seen, 
generalized  and  elucidated  by  the  action  on  the  case  for  nuisance.4 
Thus,  in  161 1,  it  was  stated  specifically  in  A/dred's  Case  that 
liability  for  nuisance  depended  on  the  principle  "  sic  utere  tuo  ut 
alienum  non  laedas  ";5  and  in  1 705,  in  the  case  of  Tenant  v.  Goldwin, 
the  rule  as  to  liability  for  cattle  trespasses  was  based  upon  the 
same  principle.  "Every  man,"  said  Holt,  C.J.,*  "must  so  use 
his  own  as  not  to  do  damage  to  another.  And  as  every  man  is 
bound  so  to  look  to  his  cattle,  as  to  keep  them  out  of  his  neigh- 
bour's ground,  that  so  he  may  receive  no  damage ;  so  he  must 
keep  in  the  filth  of  his  house  of  office,  that  it  may  not  flow  in  upon 
and  damnify  his  neighbour."  Clearly,  if  this  liability  is  put  upon 
this  proprietary  ground,  it  must  be  as  absolute  as  the  liability  for 
the  disturbance  of  possession.  This,  it  would  seem,  is  the  true 
reason  for  this  liability,  and  not  "  the  archaic  one  that  trespass 
by  a  man's  cattle  is  equivalent  to  trespass  by  himself." " 

Both  these  two  lines  of  precedents,  and  especially  the  second, 
influenced  the  decision  in  Fletcher  v.  Rylands.  The  following 
passage,  from  the  judgment  of  Blackburn,  J.,  which  was  quoted  with 
approval  by  Lord  Cairns,  proves  both  this  fact,  and  the  fact  that  the 
nature  of  the  liability  is  essentially  a  survival  of  the  general  prin- 
ciple of  liability  recognized  by  the  mediaeval  common  law  : 8  "  We 
think  that  the  true  rule  of  law  is,  that  the  person  who  for  his  own 
purposes  brings  on  his  land  and  collects  and  keeps  there  anything 
likely  to  do  mischief  if  it  escapes,  must  keep  it  at  his  peril,  and,  if 
he  does  not  do  so,  is  prima  facie  answerable  for  all  the  damage 
which  is  the  natural  consequence  of  its  escape.     He  can  excuse 

1  "  Quant  il  mit  eins  ces  beasts  en  son  commen,  luy  covient  occupier  son  commen 
issint  que  il  ne  fait  tort  a  auter  home,  et  si  le  terre  en  quel  il  doit  cest  commen  avoir, 
ne  soit  enclose,  come  est  icy,  donques  covient  de  garder  les  beasts  en  le  commen  et 
hors  de  chescun  estranger,"  Y.B.  20  Ed.  IV.  Mich.  pi.  10  per  Brian,  C.J. 

2  Vol.  iii  11.  'Above  n.  1.  *  Vol.  vii  329-330,  340-341. 
5  9  Co.  Rep.  at  f.  5ga.                 8  2  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  1092. 

7  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  504,  says,  "  observe  that  the  only  reason  given  in  the 
earlier  books  (as  indeed  it  still  prevails  in  quite  recent  cases)  is  the  archaic  one  that 
trespass  by  a  man's  cattle  is  equivalent  to  trespass  by  himself"  ;  cp.  Bl.  Comm.  iii 
211  ;  but  the  cases  cited  would  seem  to  show  that  some  of  the  judges  at  any  rate  had 
a  clear  view  of  the  true  reason  for  this  liability. 

8  (1866)  L.R.  1  Ex.  at  pp.  279-280 ;  (1868)  3  H.  of  L.  at  pp.  339-340. 


472  CRIME  AND  TORT 

himself  by  showing  that  the  escape  was  owing  to  the  plaintiffs 
default ;  or  perhaps  that  the  escape  was  the  consequence  of  vis 
major  or  the  act  of  God.  .  .  .  The  general  rule  as  above  stated 
seems  on  principle  just.  The  person  whose  grass  or  corn  is 
eaten  down  by  the  escaping  cattle  of  his  neighbour,  or  whose 
mine  is  flooded  by  the  water  from  his  neighbour's  reservoir,  or 
whose  cellar  is  invaded  by  the  filth  of  his  neighbour's  privy,  or 
whose  habitation  is  made  unhealthy  by  the  fumes  and  noisome 
vapours  of  his  neighbour's  alkali  works,  is  damnified  without  any 
fault  of  his  own ;  and  it  seems  but  reasonable  and  just  that  the 
neighbour,  who  has  brought  something  on  his  own  property  which 
was  not  naturally  there,  harmless  to  others  so  long  as  it  is  confined 
to  his  own  property,  but  which  he  knows  to  be  mischievous  if  it 
gets  on  his  neighbour's,  should  be  obliged  to  make  good  the 
damage  which  ensues  if  he  does  not  succeed  in  confining  it  to  his 
own  property."  And  then  he  went  on  to  point  out  that  the  law 
was  the  same  in  the  case  of  a  person  who  kept  a  mischievous 
animal — he  must  keep  it  at  his  peril.1  It  is  clear,  therefore,  that 
whether  we  look  at  the  nature  of  the  liability  thus  imposed,  or  at 
the  character  of  the  defences  permitted,2  the  underlying  principle 
is  the  same  as  that  which  governed  civil  liability  is  general  in  the 
mediaeval  common  law.3 

In  these  two  classes  of  cases,  therefore — the  case  where  a  man 
has  interfered  with  his  neighbour's  possession  of  or  right  to  possess 
land  or  chattels,  and  cases  coming  under  the  rule  in  Rylands  v. 
Fletcher — the  mediaeval  principle  of  civil  liability  still  holds — but 
for  reasons  very  different  from  those  on  which  it  rested  in  the 
Middle  Ages.  These  cases,  therefore,  are  two  of  the  strongest 
illustrations  of  Holmes'  aphorism  that,  "when  ancient  rules  maintain 
themselves  .  .  .  new  reasons  more  fitted  to  the  time  have  been 
found  for  them,  and  they  gradually  receive  a  new  content,  and  at 
last  a  new  form  from  the  grounds  to  which  they  have  been  trans- 
planted."4 

We  must  now  turn  from  these  cases,  in  which  the  older 
principles  have  survived  in  another  form,  to  the  case  where  a 
wholly  or  almost  wholly  new  principle  of  liability  has  been  in- 
troduced into  the  common  law. 

(3)  The  doctrine  of  Employers'  Liability.5 

Of  the  principles  applied  by  the  mediaeval  common  law  to  the 

1  L.K.  1  Ex.  at  p.  281.  2  See  as  to  this  L.Q.R.  xxv  321. 

3  Vol.  iii  375377.  378,  380. 

4  The  Common  Law  36  ;  for  another  instance  of  its  application  in  another  branch 
of  the  law  see  vol.  iii  177. 

8  Much  the  best  account  of  the  history  of  the  law  on  this  topic  will  be  found  in 
Wigmore,  op.  cit.,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  520-537. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  473 

master's  or  employer's  liability  for  the  acts  of  his  servant  I  have 
spoken  in  an  earlier  volume ; !  and  we  have  seen  that  these 
principles  were  applied  throughout  this  period.2  It  is  true  that  in 
1676,  in  the  case  of  Mitchil  v.  Alestree,  the  court  was,  on  the 
facts,  prepared  to  presume  the  existence  of  a  special  authority  to 
do  the  act — bringing  unruly  horses  into  Lincoln's  Inn  Fields — 
which  had  caused  the  damage  to  the  plaintiff3  But  it  is  clear 
from  the  case  of  Kingston  v.  Booth*  in  1685  that,  without  such 
special  authority,  the  master  could  not  be  made  liable  for  his 
servant's  torts.  In  that  case  Withins,  Holloway,  and  Walcot,  JJ., 
resolved,  firstly,  that,  "  if  I  command  my  servant  to  do  what  is 
lawful,  and  he  misbehave  himself  or  do  more,  I  shall  not  answer 
for  my  servant,  but  my  servant  for  himself,  for  that  it  was  his  own 
act ;  otherwise  it  was  in  the  power  of  every  servant  to  subject  his 
master  to  what  actions  or  penalties  he  pleased  "  ;  and,  secondly, 
"  if  I  command  my  servants  to  do  a  lawful  act  .  .  .  and  bid  them 
take  care  they  hurt  not  the^plaintiff;  if  in  this  doing  my  servants 
wound  the  plaintiff,  in  trespass  of  assault  and  wounding  brought 
against  me,  I  may  plead  not  guilty,  and  give  this  in  evidence,  for 
that  I  was  not  guilty  of  the  wounding."  It  is  clear,  therefore,  that, 
right  down  to  the  Revolution,  the  law  on  this  subject  was  sub- 
stantially the  same  as  it  was  in  the  Middle  Ages. 

But  we  have  seen  that  the  seventeenth  century  had  been  a 
century  of  expansion  and  change  in  all  branches  of  commerce  and 
industry.  Even  in  the  Middle  Ages  the  law  merchant  favoured  a 
more  extended  liability  than  that  recognized  by  the  common  law  ; 5 
and  we  have  seen  that,  in  the  earl)-  days  of  the  seventeenth 
century,  the  civil  law  rules  applied  by  the  court  of  Admiralty 
exhibited  the  same  characteristic.6  But,  as  the  result  of  the  Great 
Rebellion,  the  common  law  had  absorbed  the  greater  part  of  the 
commercial  jurisdiction  formerly  exercised  by  the  court  of  Ad- 
miralty.7 Both  the  changed  commercial  and  industrial  conditions, 
and  the  enlarged  commercial  jurisdiction  of  the  common  law  courts, 
were  making  it  clear  that  a  reconsideration  of  the  mediaeval  rules 
which  governed  this  branch  of  the  law  was  necessary.  But  the 
judges  of  the  courts  of  common  law  who  disgraced  the  bench  in 
the  latter  years  of  Charles  II. 's  and  in  James  II. 's  reigns,8  were  not 
competent  to  tackle  what  was  in  effect  a  complicated  problem  of 
law  and  public  policy.  It  was  not  till  after  the  Revolution,  when 
the  quality  of  the  bench  had  been  restored,  that  any  effort  was 
made  to  deal  with  it ;  and  fortunately  for  the  common  law  it  found 

1  Vol.  iii  382-387.  -  Above  227-228,  250. 

3  "It  shall  be  intended  the  master  sent  the  servant  to  train  the  horses  there," 
2  Lev.  at  p.  173  sub.  nom.  Michael  v.  Alestree. 

*  Skinner  228.  s  Vol.  iii  387.  6  Above  250-253. 

7  Vol.  i  556-558,  570-572  ;  vol,  v  140-148,  153-154.  8  Vol.  vi  503-511. 


474  CRIME  AND  TORT 

in  Holt,  C.J.,  a  lawyer  who,  by  reason  both  of  his  technical  equip- 
ment and  his  knowledge  of  the  commercial  needs  and  conditions 
of  the  day,  was  eminently  qualified  to  do  for  this  branch  of  the 
law  what  he  had  done  for  many  other  branches  of  commercial 
law.1 

The  reports  show  that  it  was  his  decisions  that  laid  the  founda- 
tions of  the  modern  law.  In  1691,  in  the  case  of  Boson  v.  Sand- 
ford,2  an  action  on  the  case  was  brought  by  a  shipper  of  goods 
against  the  owners  of  the  ship,  for  damage  caused  to  the  goods  by 
the  negligence  of  the  master.  Eyre,  J.,  gave  judgment  for  the 
plaintiff  on  the  narrow  ground  that  the  owners  of  the  ship  were  in 
effect  carriers,3  and  were  therefore  liable  by  reason  of  the  special 
liability  for  the  acts  of  their  servants  imposed  on  carriers  ; 4  and  it 
would  seem  that  some  reliance  was  placed  on  the  mediaeval  rules 
which  made  sheriffs  and  other  agents  of  the  crown  liable  for  the 
misdeeds  of  their  underlings.5  But  Holt  rested  his  judgment  on 
the  broad  principle  that  "whoever  employs  another  is  answerable 
for  him,  and  undertakes  for  his  care  to  all  that  make  use  of  him."  6 
In  1698,  in  the  case  of  Tuberville  v.  Stamp,1  the  plaintiff  com- 
plained that,  being  possessed  of  a  close  of  heath  adjoining  that  of 
the  defendant,  the  defendant's  servant  lit  a  fire  on  the  defendant's 
close  which  consumed  the  heath  on  his  close.  It  was  held  that  he 
had  a  good  cause  of  action.  Here  again  it  was  possible  to  ground 
the  decision  on  the  mediaeval  rules  as  to  liability  for  fire ; 8  and 
apparently  the  majority  of  the  judges  rested  their  decision  on  this 
ground.9  But  Holt  doubted  whether  the  mediaeval  rule  applied  to 
any  fires  but  those  in  houses;10  and  he  put  the  liability  upon  the 
broader  ground  that,  "if  my  servant  doth  anything  prejudicial  to 
another,  it  shall  bind  me,  when  it  may  be  presumed  that  he  acts 
by  my  authority,  being  about  my  business."  u  Similarly  in  1699 
he  ruled  at  nisi  prius  that,  if  A's  servants  driving  A's  cart  collide 
with  B's  cart  and  cause  damage,  A  is  liable ; n  and  we  have  seen 
that  in   1701,  in  the  case  of  Lane  v.  Cotton™  he  came  to  the  mis- 

1  For  an  account  of  Holt  see  vol.  vi  264-268,  270-272,  516-522. 

2  2  Salk.  440  ;  S.C.  3  Mod.  321. 

3 "  Eyre  Justice  held  there  was  no  difference  between  a  land  carrier  and  a  water 
carrier,  and  that  the  master  of  a  ship  was  no  more  than  a  servant  to  the  owners  in  the 
eye  of  the  law,"  2  Salk.  440. 

4  Vol.  iii  386.  5  3  Mod.  at  pp.  323-324  ;  for  these  rules  see  vol.  iii  387. 

6  2  Salk.  440.  7  Skinner  681  ;  S.C.  Comb.  459,  1  Ld.  Raym.  264. 

8  Vol.  iii  385.  9  1  Ld.  Raym.  264. 

10  According  to  the  report  in  Comb.  459  ;  but  according  to  the  report  in  1  Ld.  Raym. 
264  he  agreed  with  the  other  judges  on  this  point. 

11  Comb.  459  ;  in  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  pp.  264-265  Holt's  ruling  is  thus  stated,  "  if  the 
defendant's  servant  kindled  the  fire  in  the  way  of  husbandry  and  proper  for  his  employ- 
ment, though  he  had  no  express  command  of  his  master,  yet  his  master  shall  be  liable 
to  an  action  for  damage  done  to  another  by  the  fire  ;  for  it  shall  be  intended  that  the 
servant  had  authority  from  his  master,  it  being  for  his  master's  benefit." 

12  2  Salk.  441.  w  1  Salk.  17. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  475 

taken  conclusion  that  the  postmaster-general  was  liable  for  the 
loss  of  a  letter  occasioned  by  the  negligence  of  an  official  in  the 
post  office,1  on  the  authority  of  the  mediaeval  rules  which  made 
sheriffs  bailiffs  and  others  liable  for  the  misdeeds  of  their  deputies.2 
In  1709,  in  the  case  of  Hern  v.  ATichols,3  he  held  that  a  merchant 
was  liable  for  the  fraud  of  his  factor — "for  seeing  somebody  must 
be  a  loser  by  this  deceit,  it  is  more  reason  that  he  that  employs 
and  puts  a  trust  and  confidence  in  the  deceiver  should  be  a  loser 
than  a  stranger."4  From  the  first,  however,  this  liability  was 
limited  to  the  case  where  the  servant  was  about  his  master's 
business.  In  1698  it  was  held  at  nisi  prius  that  "where  a  servant 
usually  buys  for  his  master  upon  "tick,"  and  takes  up  things  in 
his  master's  name,  but  for  his  own  use,  that  the  master  is  liable, 
but  it  is  not  so  where  the  master  usually  gave  him  ready  money  "  ; 5 
and  in  1 699,  in  the  case  of  Middleton  v.  Fowler*  Holt  explained 
the  principle  to  be  that  "  no  master  is  chargeable  with  the  acts  of 
his  servant,  but  when  he  acts  in  execution  of  the  authority  given 
by  his  master,  and  then  the  act  of  the  servant  is  the  act  of  the 
master."  The  same  principle  was  again  enforced  in  1704  in  the 
case  of  Ward  v.  Evans?  At  the  same  time  other  cases  laid  it 
down,  in  conformity  with  the  mediaeval  principle,8  that  if  the 
master  had  profited  by  the  act  or  contract  of  his  servant  the  master 
was  liable.3 

It  is  clear  from  these  cases  that  the  origins  of  this  new  prin- 
ciple were  very  mixed.  But  I  think  it  probable  that  two  main 
streams  of  doctrine  contributed  to  it — firstly  a  Roman  influence 
which  filtered  through  the  court  of  Admiralty  and  mercantile 
custom,  and  secondly  an  English  influence  derived  from  the 
mediaeval  modifications  of  the  general  common  law  principle 
governing  the  master's  liability. 

(i)  We  have  seen  that  doctrines,  ultimately  derived  from  the 
Roman  learning  as  to  quasi-delict,  were  applied  in  the  court  of 
Admiralty  to  settle  the  liability  of  the  master  and  owner  of  a  ship 
to  the  shipper  and  passengers  for  the  delicts  of  the  crew,  and  the 

1  Vol.  vi  267-268.  2  Vol.  iii  387.  3  1  Salk.  289. 

4  He  gave  a  similar  explanation  of  the  rule  in  Sir  Robert  Wayland's  Case,  3  Salk. 
234 — "  the  master  is  chargeable,  for  the  master  at  his  peril  ought  to  take  care  what 
servant  he  employs  ;  and  it  is  more  reasonable  that  he  should  suffer  for  the  cheats  of 
his  servant  than  strangers." 

5  Boulton  v.  Arlsden  3  Salk.  234  ;  so  it  was  said,  ibid  at  p.  235,  that,  "  a  note  under 
the  hand  of  an  apprentice  shall  bind  his  master,  where  he  is  allowed  to  deliver  out 
notes,  though  the  money  is  never  applied  to  the  master's  use.  But  where  he  is  not 
allowed  or  accustomed  to  deliver  out  notes,  then  his  note  shall  not  bind  the  master, 
unless  the  money  is  appbed  to  the  master's  use." 

*  1  Salk.  2S2.  "  Ibid  442.  8  Vol.  iii  528. 

9  "  Where  the  master  gives  the  servant  money  to  buy  goods  for  him,  and  he  con- 
verts the  money  to  his  own  use,  and  buys  goods  upon  '  tick,'  yet  the  master  is  liable, 
so  as  the  goods  come  to  his  own  use,  otherwise  not,"  Boulton  v.  Arlsden  (169S) 
3  Salk.  324. 


476  CRIME  AND  TORT 

liability  of  the  owner  to  the  same  persons  for  the  delicts  of  the 
master.1  It  is  certainly  significant  that  the  case  of  Boson  v.  Sand- 
ford2 — the  earliest  case  in  which  the  doctrine  appears  in  a  common 
law  court — was  an  action  by  a  shipper  against  the  owner  for  damage 
suffered  by  the  master's  negligence.  Moreover  it  is  not  unlikely 
that,  as  the  necessities  arising  from  a  larger  commerce  were  felt 
in  the  court  of  Admiralty  at  an  earlier  date  than  in  the  courts  of 
common  law,  the  court  of  Admiralty  should  introduce  ideas  which 
helped  to  establish  the  new  principle  which  was  demanded  by 
those  necessities.  But  it  is  clear  that  this  was  only  one  of  the 
influences  which  went  to  the  making  of  the  modern  principle.  If 
it  had  been  the  only  influence,  probably  the  doctrine  would  have 
taken  the  form  which  the  author  of  a  recent  work  on  this  subject 
would  like  to  have  seen  it  take.  It  would  have  made  an  em- 
ployer liable  for  his  servants'  torts  only  to  those  who  were  in 
some  sort  of  contractual  relation  with  the  employer.3  But  the 
cases  of  this  period  show  that  it  was  not  so  limited  by  Holt.  Here 
again  it  is  just  possible  that  the  Roman  rules  as  to  the  actions  de 
effusis  aut  dejectis  had  some  slight  influence ; 4  but  I  think  that  it 
is  clear  that  the  influences  which  made  for  this  more  extended  rule 
came  mainly  from  the  mediaeval  common  law. 

(ii)  The  rule  which  made  householders  liable  for  damage  by 
fire  caused  by  their  servants,  appears  in  Tuberville  v.  Stamp  ; 5  and 
the  rule  as  to  common  carriers  in  Boson  v.  Sandford.6  The  rule 
that  a  man  might  be  liable  if  he  had  undertaken  to  do  something, 
and,  through  his  servant,  had  done  it  badly,7  appears  in  Wayland's 
Case ; 8  and  the  rule  that  a  master  might  be  liable  if  property 
acquired  by  his  servant  came  to  his  use  appears  in  Boulton  v. 
Arlesdn.®  Moreover  the  influence  of  this  rule  was  long  felt  in  the 
idea,  which  appears  in  Tuberville  v.  Stamp,  that  the  fact  that  the 
act  was  for  his  master's  benefit  was  a  reason  for  holding  the  master 
liable10 — an  idea  the  effects  of  which  were  not  wholly  eliminated 
till   191 2. u     The  mediaeval  rule  as  to  the  liability  of  sheriffs  and 

I  Above  250-253.  2  (1691)  2  Salk.  440. 

3  This  is  the  main  argument  of  Dr.  Baty's  ingenious  book  on  Vicarious  Liability. 

4  In  Noy's  Maxims  c.  44  it  is  said  that  "  we  shall  be  charged  if  any  of  our  family 
lay  or  cast  anything  into  the  highway  to  the  nuisance  of  his  Majesty's  liege  people  "  ; 
and  Holt,  C.J.,  in  Tuberville  v.  Stamp  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  at  p.  264  ruled  that  "  if 
my  servant  throws  dirt  into  the  highway  I  am  indictable  " ;  this  rule  is  stated  by 
Blackstone,  Comm.  i  419,  like  Noy  stated  it,  as  a  rule  which  made  a  master  liable 
for  the  acts  of  his  family;  Blackstone  compares  it  to  the  Roman  rule  set  out  in 
Institutes  4.  5.  1 ;  and  it  is  just  possible  that  that  may  be  its  origin  ;  on  the  other 
hand  it  may  be  a  solitary  survival  of  the  liability  of  the  householder  for  his 
"  mainpast,"  vol.  iii  383. 

5  (1698)  1  Ld.  Raym.  264  ;  above  474. 

8  (1691)  2  Salk.  440  ;  above  474.  7  Vol.  iii  386-387. 

8"  If  a  smith's  man  pricks  my  horse,  the  master  is  liable,"  3  Salk.  234. 

9  Ibid  ;  above  475  n.  9.  10  Above  474  n.  n. 

II  Lloyd  v.  Grace  Smith  and  Co. ^1912]  A.C.  716, 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  477 

bailiffs  and  other  officers  of  the  crown  for  the  misdeeds  of  their 
underlings,  appears  in  the  case  of  Boson  v.  SandforJ \x  and  we 
have  seen  that  it  was  the  basis  on  which  Holt  rested  his  dissenting 
judgment  in  the  case  of  Lane  v.  Cotton? 

Both  these  streams  of  doctrine  thus  joined  to  create  the  modern 
doctrine  of  employers'  liability ;  and,  as  the  technical  reasons  as- 
signed for  the  decisions  which  established  it  were  very  various,  it 
followed  that  the  basis  on  which  it  rested  was  not  at  first  clearly 
perceived.  It  was  sometimes  put  on  the  ground  that  the  master 
by  implication  undertakes  to  answer  for  his  servant's  tort — which 
is  clearly  not  true.  Sometimes  it  was  put  on  the  ground  that  the 
servant  had  an  implied  authority  so  to  act — which  again  is  clearly 
not  true.  Sometimes  it  was  grounded  on  the  fiction  that  the  wrong 
of  the  servant  is  the  wrong  of  the  master/  from  which  the  con- 
clusion was  drawn  that  the  master  must  be  liable  "  because  no 
man  shall  be  allowed  to  make  any  advantage  of  his  own  wrong"  ;4 
and  sometimes  on  the  ground  that  the  master  who  chooses  a  care- 
less servant  is  liable  for  making  a  careless  choice.5  Blackstone 
gives  all  these  reasons  for  this  principle.  In  addition,  he  deals 
with  the  totally  different  case  where  a  master  has  actually  author- 
ized the  commission  of  a  tort ;  and  cites  most  of  the  mediaeval 
cases  of  vicarious  liability  with  the  special  reasons  for  each  of 
them.0  It  is  not  surprising  that  he  should  take  refuge  in  the 
maxim  "qui  facit  per  alium  facit  per  se," "  or  that  others  should 
have  used  in  a  similar  way  the  maxim  "respondeat  superior."  s 
His  treatment  of  the  matter  illustrates  the  confusion  of  the 
authorities ;  and  it  is  noteworthy  that  he  does  not  allude  to  the 
true  reason  for  the  rule — the  reason  of  public  policy — which  Holt, 
C.J.,  gave  in  Hern  v.  Nichols  and  in  WaylancCs  Case.9 

That  this  was  the  true  reason  for  the  rule  was  only  gradually 
perceived.  As  Professor  Wigmore  has  pointed  out,  the  judges  at 
first  relied  mainly  on  the  theory  of  implied  command,10  sometimes 
classing  the  liability  as  quasi-contractual ; u  and,  considering  the 

J3  Mod.  at  pp.  323-324  ;  above  474.  2  Vol.  vi  267. 

"  Viscount  Canterbury  v.  the  Queen  (1842)  4  S.T.  N.S.  at  p.  77S  per  Lord  Lynd- 
hurst ;  Tobin  v.  the  Queen  (1864)  16  C.B.  N.S.  at  p.  350. 
4  Wigmore,  op.  cit.  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  531-532. 
'Viscount  Canterbury  v.  the  Queen  (1842)  4  S.T.  N.S.  at  p.  778. 

6  Comm.  i  417-420. 

7  "  As  for  those  things  which  a  servant  may  do  on  behalf  of  his  master,  they  all 
seem  to  proceed  upon  this  principle,  that  the  master  is  answerable  for  the  act  of  his 
servant,  if  done  by  his  command,  either  expressly  given  or  implied :  nam  qui  facit  per 
alium  facit  per  se,"  ibid  417. 

8  See  e.g.  Bartonshill  Coal  Co.  v.  Reid  (1858)  3  Macqueen  at  p.  283,  where  both 
these  Latin  tags  are  introduced  by  Lord  Cranworth ;  as  Professor  Wigmore  says, 
Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  532,  both  have  been  used  "  to  evade  giving  a  clear  reason." 

9  Above  475  and  n.  4.  10  Essays,  A.A.L.H.  iii  527. 

11  Thus  it  was  said  in  Boson  v.  Sandford  (1691)  3  Mod.  at  p.  323  that,  "  though 
the  neglect  in  this  case  was  in  the  servant,  the  action  may  be  brought  against  all  the 


478  CRIME  AND  TORT 

character  of  the  older  rule  which  this  modern  rule  had  superseded,1 
this  was  only  natural.  The  notion  of  a  liability  resting  on  an 
implied  command  could  easily  be  represented  as  a  development 
of  the  notion  of  a  liability  resting  upon  an  express  command. 
But,  at  the  end  of  the  eighteenth  and  the  beginning  of  the  nine- 
teenth centuries,  it  began  to  be  more  plainly  seen  that  this 
liability  did  not  depend  on  agency  at  all.  It  followed  that  these 
phrases  about  implied  commands  were  out  of  place.  Therefore 
the  phrases  "  scope  or  course  of  employment  or  authority  "  take 
their  place.2  This  development  helped  the  judges  at  length  to  see 
that  the  rule  rested  ultimately  on  grounds  of  public  policy.  "  The 
rule  of  liability,"  said  Lord  Brougham  in  1839,3  "and  its  reason 
I  take  to  be  this :  I  am  liable  for  what  is  done  for  me  and  under 
my  orders  by  the  man  I  employ,  for  I  may  turn  him  off  from  that 
employ  when  I  please :  and  the  reason  that  I  am  liable  is  this, 
that  by  employing  him  I  set  the  whole  thing  in  motion ;  and 
what  he  does,  being  done  for  my  benefit  and  under  my  direction, 
I  am  responsible  for  the  consequences  of  doing  it."  It  was  put 
on  the  same  grounds  by  Chief  Justice  Shaw  of  Massachusetts  : 
"  This  rule,"  he  said,4  "  is  obviously  founded  on  the  great  principle 
of  social  duty,  that  every  man  in  the  management  of  his  own 
affairs,  whether  by  himself  or  by  his  agents  or  servants,  shall  so 
conduct  them  as  not  to  injure  another ;  and  if  he  does  not,  and 
another  thereby  sustains  damage,  he  shall  answer  for  it.  If  done 
by  a  servant,  in  the  course  of  his  employment,  and  acting  within 
the  scope  of  his  authority,  it  is  considered,  in  contemplation  of  law, 
so  far  the  act  of  the  master,  that  the  latter  shall  be  answerable 
civiliter.  .  .  .  The  maxim  respondeat  superior  is  adopted  in  that 
case,  from  general  considerations  of  policy  and  security."  But 
both  in  Lord  Brougham's  and  in  Chief  Justice  Shaw's  statements 
we  can  see  traces  of  the  old  theories.  Lord  Brougham  intro- 
duces a  phrase  about  the  thing  done  being  for  the  benefit  of  the 
master ;  and  Chief  Justice  Shaw  introduces  words  which  are 
reminiscent  of  agency.  A  little  later  Lord  Cranworth,  though  he 
makes  use  of  the  same  phrases,  stated  the  principle  quite  clearly 
as  an  absolute  duty  to  guarantee  third  persons  against  hurt  aris- 
ing from  the  conduct  of  a  business.5     This   truly  describes  the 

owners,  for  it  is  grounded  quasi  ex  contractu,  though  there  was  no  actual  agreement 
between  the  plaintiff  and  them." 

1  Vol.  iii  382-385. 

2Wigmore,  Essays  A.A.L.H.  iii  533 — "the  Command  phrase  disappears  as  a 
regular  one,  and  the  Scope  of  Employment  phrase,  with  its  congeners,  come  into  full 
control." 

3  Duncan  v.  Finlater  (1839)  6  CI.  and  Fin.  at  p.  910. 

4  Farwell  v.  Boston  and  Worcester  Rly.  Corp.  (1842)  4  Met.  49,  3  Macqueen 
316. 

5  "  In  all  these  cases  the  person  injured  has  a  right  to  treat  the  wrongful  or  care- 
less act  as  the  act  of  the  master :  Qui  facit  per  alium  facit  per  se.    If  the  master  himself 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  479 

nature  of  the  liability.  As  Sir  F.  Pollock  puts  it,1  "the  liability 
of  an  employer  to  the  public  for  injuries  caused  by  the  acts  and 
defaults  of  his  servants,  is  analogous  to  the  duties  imposed  with 
various  degrees  of  stringency  on  the  owners  of  things  which  are  or 
may  be  sources  of  danger  to  others." 

We  shall  see  in  the  next  chapter  that  the  older  theory  as  to 
the  basis  of  the  liability  of  the  employer,  which  grounded  it  upon 
some  negligence  in  the  employer,  either  because  the  act  of  the 
servant  was  imputed  to  him  or  because  he  was  negligent  in 
employing  an  inefficient  servant,  has  had  some  very  unfortunate 
consequences  in  the  rules  applied  to  the  liability  of  the  crown  for 
the  acts  of  its  servants.  We  shall  see  that,  if  the  true  view  of  the 
nature  of  the  employer's  liability  had  been  reached  at  an  earlier 
date,  these  consequences  might  have  been  avoided.'2 

But  what,  if  any,  are  the  limits  to  this  absolute  duty  ?  We 
have  seen  that,  from  its  first  appearance,  the  courts  wisely  refused 
to  limit  it  by  confining  it  to  a  duty  to  compensate  only  those  who 
were  in  some  sort  of  contractual  relation  with  the  employer ; 3 
and,  in  consequence,  a  doctrine  laid  down  at  the  end  of  the 
seventeenth  century,  has  proved  capable  of  regulating  satisfactorily 
the  relations  of  employers  to  the  public  at  large  under  the 
changed  industrial  conditions  of  this  twentieth  century.^  But,  at 
the  beginning  of  the  nineteenth  century,  the  question  of  the  extent 
of  the  employer's  liability  was  raised  in  two  classes  of  cases.  The 
first  class  of  these  cases  centres  round  the  question,  Who  is  a 
servant?  The  second  class  of  these  cases  centres  round  the 
question,  What  is  the  employer's  liability  if  the  person  injured  is 
not  an  outsider  but  a  fellow-servant  of  the  tortfeasor  ? 

(i)  The  question  who  is  a  servant  for  the  purposes  of  this  rule 
does  not  seem  to  have  been  raised  till  the  end  of  the  eighteenth 
century.  In  the  case  of  Bush  v.  Steinman  4  the  court  held,  in 
effect,  that  an  employer  was  liable  for  the  acts  of  an  independent 
contractor.  But  Eyre,  C.J.,  had  considerable  doubts  as  to  the 
justice  of  imposing  such  a  liability,  because  the  actual  tortfeasor 
was   very  remotely   connected  with   the  defendant5     The    later 

had  driven  his  carriage  improperly  ...  he  would  have  been  directly  responsible,  and 
the  law  does  not  permit  him  to  escape  liability  because  the  act  complained  of  was  not 
done  with  his  own  hand.  He  is  considered  bound  to  guarantee  third  persons  against 
all  hurt  arising  from  the  carelessness  of  himself  or  of  those  acting  under  his  orders  in 
the  course  of  his  business,"  Bartonshill  Coal  Co.  v.  Reid  (1858)  3  Macqueen  at  p.  283 
per  Lord  Cranworth. 

1  Essays  in  Jurisprudence  and  Ethics  128.  2  Vol.  ix  c.  6  §  1. 

3  Above  476.  4  (1799)  1  Bos.  and  Pull.  404. 

5  "  At  the  trial  I  entertained  great  doubts  with  respect  to  the  defendant's  liability 
in  this  action.  He  appeared  to  be  so  far  removed  from  the  immediate  author  of  the 
nuisance,  and  so  far  removed  even  from  the  person  connected  with  the  immediate 


480  CRIME  AND  TORT 

cases  of  Laughter  v.  Pointer1  and  Reedie  v.  L.N.W.R}  have 
justified  these  doubts,  and  established  the  modern  rule  that  a 
master,  though  liable  for  the  acts  of  his  servant,  is  not  as  a 
general  rule  liable  for  the  acts  of  an  independent  contractor.3 
But  that  rule  is  not  without  exceptions;4  and  this  rule,  as 
mitigated  by  these  exceptions,  has  been  found  to  be  a  fair 
qualification  of  the  employer's  liability  to  the  public. 

(ii)  It  is  far  otherwise  with  the  rule  applied  by  the  common 
law  in  the  case  where  the  person  injured  by  a  servant  is  a  fellow- 
servant.  It  is  curious  that  no  case,  in  which  an  action  was 
brought  against  an  employer  for  an  injury  caused  by  one  of 
his  servants  to  another,  is  known  to  have  occurred  till  the  case 
of  Priestley  v.  Fowler?  In  1837  the  court  in  that  case  were 
unanimous  that  no  such  action  would  lie.  To  a  large  extent 
they  grounded  their  judgment  on  the  injustice  of  imposing  a  new, 
and  apparently  indefinite  series  of  liabilities,  upon  masters.6  So 
far  as  the  judgment  was  based  on  technical  reasons  it  proceeded 
on  three  grounds  :  firstly,  from  the  relation  of  master  and  servant 
there  cannot  be  implied  an  obligation  on  the  part  of  the  master  to 
take  more  care  of  the  servant  than  he  takes  of  himself;  and  any 
obligation  of  this  kind,  which  he  is  under,  is  satisfied  if  he  uses 
his  best  endeavours  to  safeguard  his  servant.  Secondly,  the 
servant,  by  entering  on  and  continuing  in  the  employment  has 
chosen  to  abide  the  risk,  of  which  he  is  likely  to  know  as  much 
if  not  more  than  the  master.  Thirdly,  to  allow  such  actions 
would  be  a  direct  incentive  "  to  omit  that  diligence  and  caution 
which  he  is  in  duty  bound  to  exercise  on  behalf  of  his  master,  to 
protect  him  against  the  misconduct  or  negligence  of  others  who 

author  in  the  relation  of  master,  that  to  allow  him  to  be  charged  for  the  injury  sus- 
tained by  the  plaintiff  seemed  to  render  a  circuity  of  action  necessary.  .  .  .  I  hesitated 
therefore  in  carrying  the  responsibility  beyond  the  immediate  master  of  the  person 
who  committed  the  injury,"  at  p.  406. 

1  (1826)  5  B.  and  C.  547.  2(l849)  4  Ex-  244- 

3  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  79-81. 

4  These  exceptional  rules  are  well   summarized   by   Underhill,   Torts   (gth  ed.) 

63-64. 

5  3  M.  and  W.  1. 

c  "  It  is  admitted  that  there  is  no  precedent  for  the  present  action  by  a  servant 
against  a  master.  We  are  therefore  at  liberty  to  decide  the  question  upon  general 
principles,  and  in  doing  so  we  are  at  liberty  to  look  at  the  consequences  of"  a  decision 
the  one  way  or  other.  If  the  master  be  liable  to  his  servant  in  this  action  the  principle 
of  that  liability  will  be  found  to  carry  us  to  an  alarming  extent.  He  who  is  respons- 
ible by  his  general  duty,  or  by  the  terms  of  his  contract,  for  all  the  consequences  of 
negligence  in  a  matter  in  which  he  is  the  principal,  is  responsible  for  the  negligence  of 
all  his  inferior  agents.  .  .  .  The  footman  who  rides  behind  the  carriage  may  have  an 
action  against  his  master  for  a  defect  in  the  carriage  owing  to  the  negligence  of  the 
coachmaker,  or  for  a  defect  in  the  harness  arising  from  the  negligence  of  the  harness 
maker,  or  for  drunkenness  neglect  or  want  of  skill  in  the  coachman,"  at  pp.  5-6  ;  the 
reasoning  is  to  some  extent  fallacious,  as  the  coachmaker  and  the  harness  maker 
would  obviously  be  independent  contractors. 


CIVIL  LIABILITY  481 

serve  him."1  This  judgment  was  followed  a  few  years  later  by 
Chief  Justice  Shaw  of  Massachusetts.2  His  judgment  is  admitted  to 
be  the  best  exposition  of  this  doctrine,  generally  called  the  doctrine 
of  common  employment,  which  had  been  first  laid  down  in  the 
case  of  Priestley  v.  Fozvler.  He  adopted  some  of  the  reasoning 
of  that  case;3  but  he  put  the  doctrine  on  a  very  much  firmer 
technical  ground.  He  pointed  out  that  the  duties  existing  as 
between  the  employer  and  his  servant  were  purely  contractual. 
They  were  governed  entirely  by  the  contract.  The  contract  con- 
tained no  express  clause  by  which  the  master  undertook  to  indemnify 
the  servant  against  the  act  of  his  fellow-servant,  and  no  such  term 
could  be  implied.  On  the  other  hand,  the  duties  existing  as 
between  the  employer  and  the  public  were  not  contractual,  and 
the  law  had  determined  that  a  duty  to  indemnify  the  public  for 
the  torts  committed  by  his  servant  in  the  course  of  his  employ- 
ment did  exist.4  There  was  thus  a  good  technical  reason  for 
drawing  this  distinction  between  liability  for  wrongs  committed 
by  servants  against  fellow-servants,  and  wrongs  committed  by 
servants  against  outsiders ;  for,  in  the  former  case,  the  rights  of 
the  master  and  servant,  having  been  fully  settled  by  their  con- 
tract, no  place  was  left  for  any  other  liabilities  not  contemplated 
by  the  contract  Moreover,  this  reasoning  answered  the  objection 
that,  in  a  large  undertaking,  a  servant  has  no  more  means  of  control 
over  a  fellow-servant  than  any  other  member  of  the  public — "  the 
master  in  the  case  supposed  is  not  exempt  from  liability,  because 
the  servant  has  better  means  of  providing  for  his  safety,  when  he 
is  employed  in  immediate  connexion  with  those  from  whose 
negligence  he  might  suffer ;  but  because  the  implied  contract  of 
the  master  does  not  extend  to  indemnify  the  servant  against  the 
negligence  of  anyone  but  himself;  and  he  is  not  liable  in  tort,  as 
for  the  negligence  of  his  servant,  because  the  person  suffering  does 
not  stand  towards  him  in  the  relation  of  a  stranger,  but  is  one 
whose  rights  are  regulated  by  contract  express  or  implied. " 5 

But,  after  all,  these  decisions  to  a  large  extent  ignored  the 
conditions  of  modern  industry.  However  good  the  technical 
reasons  which  could  be  adduced  for  the  doctrine,  it  was  quite  clear 
that,  in  a  great  undertaking  like  a  railway,  a  servant  has  as  little 
opportunity  of  guarding  against  the  negligence  of  many  of  his  fellow- 
servants  as  a  member  of  the  public ;  and  he  could  hardly  be  said 
to  have  consented  to  abide  risks  of  which  he  had  neither  know- 
ledge nor  means  of  knowledge.  The  limitation  thus  imposed  on 
the   liability  of  employers  was   far  too  strict — a  truth  which   is 

1  At  p.  7. 

3  Farwell  v.  Boston  and  Worcester  Rly.  Corp.  (1842)  4  Met.  49,  3  Macqueen  316. 
3  3  Macqueen  at  pp.  317-319.  *  Ibid  at  p.  317.  5  Ibid  at  p.  320. 

VOL.  VIII. — 31 


482  CRIME  AND  TORT 

emphasized  by  the  fact  that  no  other  country  in  Europe  has 
adopted  any  similar  doctrine.1  In  these  latter  days  the  result 
of  this  over-strictness  has  been  that  the  Legislature  has  imposed 
a  liability  on  employers,  which  errs  almost  as  much  in  the 
direction  of  liberality.  For  under  the  modern  Workmen's  Com- 
pensation Act'2  a  workman,  though  he  has  voluntarily  entered  the 
particular  business,  is  better  protected  from  the  risks  incident  to 
its  conduct  than  a  member  of  the  public — an  extravagant  degree 
of  protection,  which  obviously  removes  one  of  the  chief  incentives 
to  carefulness  on  the  part  of  the  servant. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  development  of  the  law  of  crime  and 
tort,  during  this  period  and  in  the  succeeding  centuries,  has  been 
affected,  almost  as  much  as  the  law  of  contract,  by  the  new 
influences  which  began  to  be  felt  during  this  period.  The  new 
territorial  state  and  its  larger  control  over  the  actions  of  its 
subjects,  the  new  relations  between  church  and  state,  the  growth 
of  industry  and  commerce — all  had  a  large  influence  in  shaping 
these  branches  of  the  law.  Much  that  was  mediaeval  was 
retained,  and  more  was  made  the  foundation  of  an  elaborate 
superstructure  of  rules,  which,  in  many  cases,  have  in  effect 
created  entirely  new  bodies  of  law.  Much  that  was  admittedly 
wholly  new  was  added  to  meet  new  needs  and  new  problems. 
Though  in  the  criminal  law  too  many  antiquated  rules  both  of 
substantive  and  adjective  law  were  retained,  yet,  on  the  whole, 
the  professional  developments  of  this  period  ifl  the  law  both  of 
crime  and  of  tort  are  a  credit  to  the  common  law.  As  we  can 
see  from  the  later  history  of  many  of  the  branches  of  law 
which  I  have  sketched  in  this  chapter,  they  have  resulted  in  the 
creation  of  a  body  of  principles  which  has  proved  to  be  at  once 
flexible  and  permanent — a  body  of  principles,  which,  on  the 
whole,  has  met  adequately  the  constantly  new  needs  of  a  pro- 
gressive and  expanding  state. 

At  this  point,  to  adapt  the  phraseology  of  the  Roman  Institutes, 
I  leave  the  history  of  the  technical  development  of  the  law  of 
Things,  and  turn  to  the  corresponding  development  of  the  law  of 
Persons. 

1  Pollock,  Torts  (12th  ed.)  101,  and  see  93  n.  (f). 
a6  Edward  VII.  c.  58. 


INDEX 


Abbott  (Lord  Tenterden),  249,  264,  265, 

266,  267. 
Acceptance  for  Honour,  156. 
Acceptor,   The,  original  nature  of  his 

liability  to  the  drawer,  138,  161-162 ; 

his  liability  to  the  payee,  138-139,  140, 

144,  162. 
Accessories,  305. 


Agency,  222-229 ;  unknown  to  primitive 
systems  of  la%v,  222 ;  agents  to  acquire 
property,  222 ;  to  contract,  222-224  ;  see 
Brokers,  Factors;  liability  of  principal 
for  acts  of  agent — the  mediaeval  prin- 
ciple, 227-228 ;  need  for  change — Holt's 
decisions,  22g,  252-253,  474-475 ;  prin- 
ciples applied  by  the  Admiralty,  249- 
252 ;  their  influence  on  the  common 
law,  253  ;  see  Employers'  Liability. 


Accident,  how  it  came  to  be  a  defence  to   Agreement,  the  essence  of  contract,  1 ; 


an  action  for  trespass,  456,  457-458. 

Accident  Insurance,  character  of,  295  ; 
not  known  in  the  sixteenth  and  seven- 
teenth centuries,  295-296  ;  beginnings 
of  in  England,  297-298. 

Accommodation  Paper,  169. 

Accord  and  Satisfaction,  why  satis- 
faction was  needed,  82-83 ;  payment  of 


in  continental  law,  43,  44-45 ;  contrast 
with  English  law,  46-47 ;  how  greater 
weight  might  be  given  to  in  English 
law,  48 ;  operation  of  in  discharge  of 
contract,  80-88 ;  effect  of  on  a  contract 
under  seal,  80-81 ;  on  a  simple  contract, 
S1-S5  ;  see  Accord  and  Satisfaction ;  the 
effect  of  a  novation,  85-87. 


a  lesser  sum  not  valid  as,  40,  83  ;  effect  Alien  Enemies,  insurances  on  goods  of, 

on  these  rules  of  growth  of  validity  of  291. 

executory  contracts,  40-41,  83-84 ;   un-  Aliens,  made  liable   to   the  bankruptcy 

certainty  as  to  the  law,  84-85.  laws,  237. 

Account,  action  of,  influence  on  doctrine  Alteration  of  a  written  contract,  effect 

of  consideration  of  the  idea  that  it  lies  of,  64-65. 

for  third  persons  to  whose  use  money  is  Ames,  85,  92. 

paid,  13 ;   used  to   enforce  quasi-con-  Amsterdam,  bank  of,  i8o-i8r,  183  ;  con- 
tractual relations,  88.  trasted  with  the  Bank  of  England,  188. 
Act   of   God,    defence  to  an  action  of  Anderson,  C.J. ,  57,  389. 

trespass,  455;  expansion  of  this  idea,  Anglo-Saxon,  Land  Books,  118;  laws  as 

455-456-  to  defamation,  334-335. 

Actio  Personalis,  etc.,   application   of  Animals,  liability  for  trespasses  of,  456- 

to  trover,  38.  457,  465-466,  470-471 ;  for  damage  done 

Acts  of    Bankruptcy,   237-238;    juris-  by,  469-470;  see  Wild  Animals. 

diction  to  determine,  240-241.  Ansaldus,  142. 

Adequacy,  not  needed  for  a  valid  con-  Anti-Christian  Beliefs,  405,  408-409, 

sideration,  17.  410,  413-414,  414-417,  420. 

Administratob,  validity  of  promise  of  Anvers,  the  fairs  of,  129. 

to  pay  debts  and  legacies,  27-28,  30.  Apostasy,  408. 

Admiralty,  court  of,  instruments  payable  Apprentices,   contracts    in   restraint  of 

to  bearer  or  attorney  en  the  records  of,  trade  imposed  on,  59,  61,  62. 

148  ;  bills  of  exchange  on  the  records  Aquinas,  103. 

of,    152 ;   its  jurisdiction  in  insurance  Arabic  Law,  suggested  origin  of  bill  of 

cases,  283-284,  288;    rules  as  to  insur-  exchange  in,  133-134;  influence  of  on 


ance  evolved  by,  290-291 ;  influence  of 
law  administered  by  on  doctrine  of 
employers'  liability,  475-476. 

Admiralty  Droits,  269. 

Adstipulatio,  132,  133. 


European  commercial  law,  133. 
Aristotle,  views  of  as  to  usury,  101. 
Arrest,  of  a  ship,  effect  of  Admiralty 

process  of  on  the  maritime  lien,  271, 

272-273. 


Affirmation,  allowed  in  place  of  an  oath,  Arson,  305. 

413,  416.  Ashley,  Sir  W.,  101,  103,  104,  105,  107. 

Affrays,  326.  Asportation,  of  chattels,  absolute  lia- 

African  Company,  The,  209,  210.  bility  for,  466-468. 

483 


484 


INDEX 


Assault  and  Battery,  421-423. 

Assignment,  power  of  commissioners  in 
bankruptcy  to  make  an,  239;  relation 
back  of  title  to  act  of  bankruptcy,  240  ; 
validity  of  if  made  before  bankruptcy, 
242. 

Assumpsit,  action  of  familiarizes  lawyers 
with  the  idea  of  an  enforceable  agree- 
ment, 1 ;  elements  in  consideration  due 
to,  2-3  ;  facts  needed  to  establish  cause 
of  action  in,  called  consideration,  4,  6-7  ; 
express,  8 ;  indebitatus,  8 ;  has  shaped 
the  English  theory  of  contract,  46 ;  its 
effect  on  the  law  of,  46-47  ;  has  shaped 
law  as  to  invalidity  enforcement  and 
breach  of  contract,  87-88;  a  plaintiff 
must  show  performance  as  a  condition 
of  recovery  by  action  of,  72 ;  used  to 
enforce  rights  of  the  parties  to  a  bill  of 
exchange,  159-160. 

Astbury,  J.,  395. 

Atheism,  see  Anti-Christian  Beliefs. 

Atkin,  L.J.,  395,  396,  466. 

Attempts  to  commit  crimes,  434. 

Attorney,  promises  to  pay  creditor's  at- 
torney, 116-118,  119-121;  an  agent  for 
litigation,  222. 

Average,  see  General  Average ;  custom- 
ary payments  called  by  that  name,  255. 


15 


Bacon,  his  views  on  usury,  108  ;  312,  313, 
314,  446,  453,  454,  464- 

Bagehot,  100,  188,  214. 

Bailee,  liability  of  at  common  law,  259  ; 
basis  of  his  liability,  452. 

Baldus,  126. 

Baldwin,  C.J.,  424. 

Bank  of  England,  135-136,  183,  188- 
189,  203,  2og;  liability  of  shareholders 
in,  205  ;  incorporation  of,  211-212,  218  ; 
offer  to  take  over  the  national  debt, 
212;  notes  of  the,  191. 

Bank  Notes,  190- igi ;  payment  by,  191- 
192. 

Bankers,  act  as  exchangers,  127;  used 
by  the  merchants  to  effect  a  transport 
of  money,  129-130. 

Banking,  177-192;  origins  of,  177-178; 
comparison  of  origins  of,  with  origins 
of  bills  of  exchange,  130 ;  uses  made  of 
banks,  178-179  ;  political  importance  of, 
179-180;  state  control  of,  180-181 ; 
state  banks,  181-182;  sixteenth  and 
seventeenth  century  descriptions  of, 
182-183 ;  proposals  to  establish  banks 
in  England,  183-184;  not  definitely 
organized  in  Elizabeth's  reign,  185 ; 
private  banking — becomes  connected 
with  the  goldsmiths,  185-186;  why  no 
public   bank  was   established   till   the 


Revolution,  186-188;  establishment  of 
the  Bank  of  England,  188-189;  its 
services  to  the  government,  189  ;  be- 
ginnings of  law  as  to,  189-192;  effect 
of  on  development  of  joint  stock  com- 
panies in  Italy,  208 ;  see  Cheques, 
Bank  Notes. 

Bankrupt,  promises  to  pay  by  a,  26,  27, 
31 ;  estate  of  a — rule  of  rateable  division, 
239,  242  ;  of  what  it  consisted,  239-240 ; 
after-acquired  property  of,  239  ;  equit- 
able interests  and  settled  property  of, 
241,  242 ;  see  Voluntary  Conveyances, 
Reputed  Ownership. 

Bankruptcy,  229-245  ;  Italian  develop- 
ment of  law  of,  229-230  ;  not  known  in 
England  till  the  sixteenth  century,  229- 
233  ;  the  Council  and  the  unfortunate 
debtor,  233-234 ;  bad  effects  of  the 
abolition  ot  its  jurisdiction,  245  ;  seven- 
teenth-century legislation  as  to  un- 
fortunate debtors,  234-236  ;  measures 
against  dishonest  debtors,  236 ;  these 
measures  are  the  origin  of  the  bank- 
ruptcy law,  236-237;  Henry  VIII. 's 
Act,  236-237 ;  Elizabeth's  and  James  I.'s 
Acts,  237-240 ;  persons  who  can  be- 
come bankrupt,  237;  acts  of,  237-238, 
240-241 ;  jurisdiction  in,  238  ;  powers 
and  duties  of  commissioners  in,  238- 
239 ;  assets  available  for  distribution  in, 
239-240 ;  effect  of  on  bankrupt's  lia- 
bility, 240;  policy  of  the  statutes  of, 
240;  issue  of  commissions  in,  241; 
cases  on  the  statutes  of,  241-242  ;  joint 
and  separate  estates  of  bankrupt 
partners,  242-243 ;  vendor's  lien,  243 ; 
stoppage  in  transitu,  243 ;  defects  of 
the  statutes  of,  243-244 ;  need  for  the 
chancellor's  interference,  244 ;  unsatis- 
factory state  of  the  law,  244-245 ; 
actions  for  imputation  of,  349,  355  ;  see 
Compositions  with  Creditors. 

Banks,  private  and  public — abroad,  180, 
181-182 ;  in  England,  185-189. 

Barbon,  Nicholas,  294. 

Barbour,  42. 

Barcelona,  its  code  of  insurance  law, 
281 ;  historical  importance  of  this  code, 
281-282  ;  its  contents,  282-283. 

Bardi,  the,  178,  207. 

Battery,  see  Assault  and  Battery. 

Bearer,  position  of  bearer  of  old  instru- 
ments payable  to  their  producers,  117, 
118,  121-124;  effect  of  making  bills 
payable  to  in  early  seventeenth  century, 
154-155,  156,  157, 164-165  ;  recognition 
of  rights  of  helps  to  establish  the  main 
feature  of  negotiability,  165-166;  notes 
payable  to  not  assignable  in  seventeenth 
century,  171 ;  effect  of  statute  as  to 
notes  on  bills  to  bearer,  176. 

Beaumont,  J.,  389. 


INDEX 


483 


Beneficium  Competenti.5,  as  between 
partners,  195. 

Benbfit  of  Clergy,  444. 

Benefit  to  Promisor,  not  an  essential 
element  in  consideration,  10-11;  con- 
fusion caused  by  regarding  it  as  such, 
24. 

Bensa,  261,  262,  274,  275,  276,  283,  296, 
297. 

Bentham,  100. 

Berkley,  J.,  81. 

Bermuda  Company,  The,  209. 

Beven,  464. 

Bills  of  Conformity,  244. 

Bills  of  Debt,  148-151;  proposal  to 
make  them  assignable,  171. 

Bills  of  Exchange,  Continental  origins  [ 
and  development — the  contract  of  cam- 
bium, 126- 13 1 ;  machinery  to  give  effect 
to  that  variety  of  the  contract  which 
concerned  the  transport  of  money,  131- 
132 ;  this  is  the  probable  origin  of  these 
bills,  132, 136-137  ;  other  suggestions  as 
to  origins  of,  132-136;  relations  of  the  ! 
parties  to,  137-140 ;  see  Drawer,  Ac-  \ 
ceptor,  Payee,  Indorsee ;  development  of 
their  negotiable  character,  140  145 ; 
The  English  development — introduction 
from  abroad,  151 ;  reception  of  foreign 
doctrine  as  to,  155-156, 161 ;  early  forms 
of,  152-153;  parties  to,  153-154;  how 
negotiated,  154-155  ;  Marius's  account ' 
of,  155-157  ;  how  far  negotiable  in  the  j 
seventeenth  century,  157-158;  inland 
and  outland  bills,  158 ;  application  of 
assumpsit  to  enforce  the  rights  of 
the  parties  to,  159-160;  use  made  of 
mercantile  custom,  160-161 ;  relations 
of  the  parties  to,  161-163  ;  development 
of  the  negotiable  character  of,  163- 
168 ;  peculiarities  of  the  English  law  as 
to,  169-170  ;  payable  to  a  named  payee 
only,  156 ;  indorsement  of  induced  by 
fraud,  51 ;  cheques  a  variety  of,  190. 

Bills  of  Lading,  254,  255-257  ;  origins, 
255-256  ;  drawn  in  sets  of  three,  256 ; 
assignability  of,  257 ;  why  not  negoti- 
able, 257 ;  stoppage  in  transitu,  243,  257. 

Bills  Obligatory,  see  Bills  of  Debt. 

Bills  of  Sale,  ships  conveyed  by,  246. 

Birkenhead,  Lord,  418. 

Blackburn,  Lord,  417,  456,  471. 

Blackstone,  his  views  as  to  quasi-con- 
tract, 96 ;  as  to  employer's  liability, 
477;  227,  326,  373,  377,  409,  414,  416, ; 

441.  454- 
Blasphemy,  333,  337,  405.  407-409,  411, 

413-414,  414-416. 
Blencowe,  J.,  S6. 
Boatsman,  the,  248. 
Bona  Fide  holder  for  value,  of  a  bill  of 

exchange,  position   of  in   seventeenth 

century,  157-158,  165-167. 


Bonds,  imposing  restraints  on  trade,  59, 
60 ;  assimilated  by  the  merchants  to 
bills  of  exchange,  175. 

Bosanquet  and  Puller,  their  note  on 
consideration,  36-38. 

Bottomry,  loans  on,  261263;  origins, 
261-262 ;  confer  a  lien,  262 ;  come  to 
entail  no  personal  liability,  262-263 ' 
risks  undertaken  by  the  lender,  263  ;  re- 
lation of  to  marine  insurance,  277 ;  usury 
laws  not  applicable  to,  104 ;  master's 
power  to  hypothecate  ship  cargo  or 
freight  a  variety  of,  249. 

Bowen,  L.J.,  39,  56. 

Bracton,  53,  80,  102,  439,  452. 

Bradlaugh,  413. 

Brian,  C.J.,  20,  454. 

Brinklow,  his  criticisms  on  the  law  as  to 
execution  for  debt,  232,  245. 

Brissaud,  43,  145. 

Brokers,  102-103,  224-225,  225,  279. 

Brooke,  J.,  324. 

Brougham,  Lord,  478. 

Brunner,  116,  121,  141. 

Bubble  Act,  the,  220,  its  good  and  bad 
effects,  220-221 ;  legal  problems  raised 
by  its  repeal,  221. 

Buller,  J.,  28,  29,  87. 

Burglary,  304-305. 

Burke,  383. 

burlamachi,  183. 

Business,  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade 
on  the  sale  of  a,  58,  59,  62. 

Byelaws,  action  of  debt  for  breach  of, 
88  ;  indebitatus  assumpsit  for  breach  of, 
90 ;  Holt's  ineffectual  opposition,  90- 
92. 


Cairns,  Lord,  471. 

Calimala,  Florentine  statute  of  the,  132. 

Calvin,  his  views  as  to  usury*,  109. 

Cambium,  the  contract  of,  126  ;  minutum, 
126-127  '■>  siccum  or  fictivum,  127-128  ; 
the  agreement  for  the  transport  of 
money,  128 ;  origin  of  the  modern 
mechanism  of  exchange  and  banking, 
128 ;  how  developed  for  this  purpose, 
129-130;  use  of  in  England,  130-131 ; 
machinery  for  giving  effect  to  it,  131- 
132;  letters  of  payment,  132-136;  the 
instrumentum  ex  causa  cambii,  132, 
136-137  ;  insurances  disguised  as  con- 
tracts of,  275-276. 

Campsores,  the  earliest  bankers,  177, 
178. 

Candler,  Richard,  286,  287. 

Canon  Law,  influence  of  on  doctrine  of 
consideration  as  applied  in  the  Chancery 
to  contract  and  uses,  5 ;  influence  of 
theory  of  causa  in  en  continental  codes, 
42-43  ;  influence  on  law  of  agency,  223  ; 


486 


INDEX 


as  to  usury,  101 ;  the  law  of  the  Eng- 
lish Church  in  the  Middle  Ages,  402. 
Caorsini,  the,  177. 

Capias,  ad  respondendum,  231 ;  ad  satis- 
faciendum, 231. 
Capital,  trading  with  borrowed,  helped 
by  growth  of  banking,  i8g  ;  utilization 
Of  by  means  of  joint  stock  companies, 
205,  207-208;  hindered  by  the  Bubble 
Act,  221 ;  hazy  ideas  as  to  nature  of, 
217;  dividends  paid  out  of,  216-217. 
Carr,  199. 

Carriage,    the     contract     of,    254-261 ; 
incidents   of,  261-273 ;    see   Bottomry, 
General    Average,    Salvage,    Maritime 
Liens. 
Carriers,  duties  of  enforced  by  actions  on 
the  case,  89;    liability   of  at   common 
law,    259,   452-453 ;    in    the    court    of 
Admiralty,  259 ;  449,  474,  476. 
Case,  actions  on  the,  brought  by  persons 
to  whose  use  property   has    been  con- 
veyed, 222  ;  how  they  helped  to  intro- 
duce the  idea  of  negligence,  449-451. 
Cattle  Trespass,  liability  for  451-452, 

470-471. 
Causa,  in  continental  law,  42-45  ;  writing 

as  a,  45-46. 
Cautiones,  ex  causa  cambii,  136-137. 
Caveat  Emptor,  69. 
Certainty,  needed  in  a  consideration,  17- 

18. 
Cessio    Bonorum,    Roman    system    of 

adopted  in  the  Italian  cities,  230. 
Champagne,  the  fairs  of,  129. 
Chancery,  the  court  of,  effect  given  by 
to  an  agreement,  1 ;  elements  in  con- 
sideration due  to,  3  ;  meaning  attached 
to  consideration  by,  4-5 ;   influence  of 
this  meaning  on  common  law  doctrine, 
7-8,    12-13;    early   case   on   a   bill   of 
exchange  in,  152  ;  jurisdiction  in  insur- 
ance cases,  2g2,  293. 
Charter  Parties,  254,  255. 
Charters,   of  trading  companies,  con- 
tents    of    early,     200-201 ;    questions 
whether  their  activities  were  limited  by 
their,    215,    216 ;     trade    in    obsolete 
charters,  215-216. 
Cheques,  190-191 ;  payment  by,  191. 
Choses  in  Action,  why  not  assignable 
in    early   law,    115,    147,    150;    partly 
caused   by  fear   of  maintenance,  398 ; 
how  the  prohibition  against  assignment 
was     evaded,    117-118 ;     transfers     of 
documents  allowed  to  operate  as  trans- 
fers of,  118-119. 
Christianity,    offences    against,    402 ; 
how  far   a   part  of  English  law,  403, 
405,  408,  409,  410,  413. 
Church   and   State,  relations  of,  402, 

403-404,  406-408,  418,  420. 
Clerk  of  a  Ship,  the,  248. 


Cloth  Trade,  connection  of  with  bank- 
ing business,  185. 

Code  Napoleon,  the,  43. 

Coercion,  how  far  a  defence  to  a  charge 
of  crime,  443. 

Cohen,  Arthur,  394. 

Coke,  10,  18,  19,  22,  24,  36,  50,  52,  58, 
79,  80,  81,  82,  227,  259,  308,  311,  312, 
3!3,  314.  315.  3*9.  323.  326,  336,  339. 
355.  368,  38°.  386,  397.  399.  4°9,  435. 
439,  441,  451,  452;  his  views  on  the 
policy  of  the  bankruptcy  acts,  240. 

Coleridge,  J.,  415. 

Coleridge,  Lord,  C.J.,  410,  415. 

Collision,  266-269 ;  scantiness  of  early 
law,  266  ;  the  modern  rules,  266;  cases 
rare  in  the  sixteenth  century,  267 ; 
reason  for  this,  267 ;  cases  where  the 
loss  is  divided,  267,  268 ;  logical  nature 
of  the  Admiralty  rules  as  to,  268-269. 

Colloquium,  the,  369. 

Colonization,  companies  for  201,  209; 
their  disappearance,  209-210. 

Combinations,  danger  of  to  the  state, 
332,  382-383  ;  of  employers  and  work- 
men, 392. 

Commenda,  contract  of  used  to  evade  the 
prohibition  of  usury,  104  ;  its  nature, 
195-196 ;  influence  of  on  English  law, 
197  ;  stipulations  as  to  risk  in,  275  ;  138. 

Commerce  and  Industry,  wrongs  con- 
nected with,  430-431. 

Commercial  Law,  99-245  ;  see  Usury, 
Negotiable  Instruments,  Banking,  Com- 
mercial Societies,  Agency,  Bankruptcy ; 
influence  on  of  state  needs,  135-136. 

Commercial  Societies,  192-222 ;  varie- 
ties of,  192-193  ;  early  forms  of — gilds, 
193 ;  influence  of  gilds  on  later  com- 
panies, 193-194;  the  commenda,  195- 
196 ;  why  it  did  not  take  root  in 
England,  196-197 ;  the  societias,  197- 
199 ;  the  firm  is  not  a  separate  person 
in  English  law,  198-199,  see  Partner- 
ship;  application  of  corporate  idea 
to — advantages,  199,  200-205,  213-214; 
early  companies,  199-200 ;  joint  stock 
and  regulated  companies,  206-213,  see 
Companies,  South  Sea  Company  ;  scanti- 
ness of  rules  of  law  applicable  to,  215, 
217-218  ;  effects  of  this,  215-217,  218  ; 
state  encouragement  to  speculation  in 
shares  of,  218,  219  ;  the  Bubble  Act, 
219-221 ;  effects  of  its  repeal,  221. 
Commission  of  Bankruptcy,  the   issue 

of,  234,  241. 
Commissioners  in  Bankruptcy,  238 ; 
controlled  by  the  Chancery,  238,  244 ; 
by  courts  of  common  law,  240-241 ; 
powers  of,  238-239 ;  duties  of  to  credi- 
tors and  the  bankrupt,  239,  240,  241 ; 
incompetence  of,  243-244  ;  liability  of, 
244. 


INDEX 


487 


Commissioners  for  Insurance  Cases, 
287-288 ;  why  a  failure,  288. 

Commissioners  of  Trade,  214. 

Common  Employment,  the  doctrine  of, 
480-482. 

Common  Law  Commissioners,  views  as 
to  law  of  bankruptcy,  245. 

Common  Law  Courts,  jurisdiction  in  in- 
surance cases,  288  ;  rules  as  to  insur- 
ance evolved  by,  291-292  ;  why  defect- 
ive tribunals  for  these  cases,  292-293  ; 
effect  on  the  law,  293. 

Companies,  influence  on  of  gild  tradi- 
tion, 192-194 ;  joint  stock  and  regulated, 
194,  202,  205,  206;  advantages  of  in- 
corporation, 199 ;  companies  of  four- 
teenth, fifteenth  and  early  sixteenth 
centuries,  199-200 ;  why  they  were 
incorporated,  200-202 ;  commercial  ad- 
vantages of  incorporation,  202-203 ; 
liability  of  their  members  to  creditors, 
203 ;  liability  to  the  company — levi- 
ations,  204;  limitation  of  liability, 
204-205  ;  transition  from  regulated  to 
joint  stock  form,  206-207  ;  origins  of 
joint  stock  principle,  207-20S ;  incor- 
poration of  large  partnerships,  208  209  ; 
need  to  organize  trade  and  colonization, 
209;  later  history  of  these  companies, 
209-211 ;  use  made  of  joint  stock  prin- 
ciple to  borrow  money — the  Bank  of 
England  and  the  South  Sea  Company, 
211-213  ;  commercial  advantages  of  this 
principle,  213-214;  rise  of  a  market  for 
shares,  214  ;  phenomena  of  speculation, 
214-215 ;  no  clear  line  between  cor- 
porations and  partnerships,  215;  scanti- 
ness of  the  law,  215-216  ;  no  principle 
of  ultra  vires,  216;  irregular  accounts, 
216 ;  rights  as  against  a  dissolved 
company,  217 ;  encouragement  of 
speculation  by  the  state,  218-219 !  the 
Bubble  Act  and  its  effects,  219-221 ;  help 
forward  growth  of  a  law  of  agency,  223. 

Compositions  with  Creditors,  how 
reconciled  with  the  doctrine  of  consid- 
eration, 85 ;  enforced  by  the  Council, 
233-234 ;  loss  of  this  power,  244,  245  ; 
bad  results  of  this,  245. 

Compulsion,  how  far  a  defence  to  a 
criminal  charge,  444-445. 

Comyns,  22,  373. 

Concurrent  Conditions,  effect  of  on 
the  law  as  to  enforcement  of  contracts, 
74-75  ;  failure  of  performance  by  breach 
of,  77. 

Condemnation,  of  ships,  246. 

Conditions,  effect  of  the  breach  of,  77,  78. 

Conscience,  a  ground  for  enforcing 
agreements,  27-28  ;  see  Moral  Obliga- 
tion. 

Consent,  absence  of  a  cause  of  invalidity 
of  a  contract,  50-51. 


Consideration,  evolution  of  the  term,  3- 
8 ;  use  of  by  the  common  law  in  fifteenth 
and  early  sixteenth  centuries,  4 ;  use 
of  by  the  Chancery,  4-5  ;  not  a  technical 
word  in  early  sixteenth  century,  5-6 ; 
gains  a  technical  meaning  in  connection 
with  assumpsit,  6-7  ;  but  influenced  by 
other  ideas,  7-8 ;  mutual  promises,  9 ; 
precedent  debt,  9-10,  see  Past  Con- 
sideration ;  detriment  to  promisee,  10- 
11 ;  must  move  from  promisee  but  need 
not  move  to  promisor,  n-13  ;  executory 
or  executed,  13-14 ;  past  and  executed, 
14-16,  38-40;  adequacy,  17;  certainty, 
18;  must  be  of  some  value,  18-24; 
forbearance  to  prosecute,  18- ig  ;  release 
or  promise  to  release  a  debt,  19-23, 
40-41 ;  performance  or  promise  to  per- 
form a  contractual  duty,  23-24,  41,  84 ; 
growth  of  idea  in  eighteenth  century 
that  moral  obligation  is  a,  26-29,  30- 
33 ;  influence  on  of  mercantile  law  in 
eighteenth  century,  29-30 ;  probable 
results  on  the  doctrine  of,  34 ;  rejection 
of  these  eighteenth  century  ideas,  34- 
38 ;  results  on  the  modern  doctrine, 
38-42  ;  comparison  of  with  the  contin- 
ental "  cause  "  42-46 ;  strong  and  weak 
points  of,  46-47 ;  why  the  doctrine  is 
an  anachronism,  46-47  ;  strong  points 
of  the  eighteenth  century  views,  47-48  ; 
how  the  doctrine  might  be  reformed, 
48 ;  effect  of  illegality  of,  53 ;  rules 
as  to  in  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade, 
59,  62 ;  application  of  doctrine  to  dis- 
charge of  contract,  82-85  ;  remedy  in 
case  of  total  failure  of,  93-94,  97  ;  ap- 
plication of  doctrine  of  to  bills  of 
exchange,  167-168;  presumption  of  as 
against  an  acceptor  of  a  bill  of  exchange, 
143,  167. 

CONSOLATO    DEL  MARE,  28l. 

Conspiracy,  378-397  ;  influences  which 
formed  the  law  of,  378-379  ;  effect  on 
of  the  abolition  of  the  Star  Chamber, 
361-364;  The  Crime,  379-384;  the  gist 
of  the  offence,  380-381 ;  meaning  of 
the  term  "  unlawful  act,"  3S1 ;  origin 
of  wide  definition  of  the  crime,  382 ; 
why  expedient  that  it  should  be  wide, 
382-383  ;  connection  with  public  policy, 
383-384;  the  statutory  writ  and  the 
action  on  the  case  for,  385-391,  see 
Malicious  Prosecution ;  The  Tort,  392- 
397 ;  why  it  developed  later,  392 ; 
relation  to  the  crime,  392-394  ;  relation 
to  the  statutory  writ  and  the  action  on 
the  case,  393 ;  conflicting  views  as  to 
in  modern  cases,  394-396 ;  the  modern 
law,  395-397- 

Conspiracy  to  Levy  War,  when  treason, 
313,  314.  318-319. 

Constitutional  Society,  the,  318. 


488 


INDEX 


CONSTITUTUM  DEBITI  ALIENI,  137. 

Construction,  of  defamatory  words, 
358-359 ;  bad  effect  of  reporting  cases 
as  to  the,  359-360. 

Constructive  Treason,  see  Treason. 

Contarini,  179. 

Contract,  its  essence,  1 ;  need  to  dis- 
tinguish enforceable  from  unenforceable 
agreements,  1-2,  see  Consideration ; 
causes  of  invalidity  of,  49-65,  see  Mis- 
take, Duress,  Illegality,  Impossibility, 
Fraud,  Misrepresentation,  Alteration; 
effects  of  invalidity,  65-67,  see  Void, 
Voidable,  Unenforceable ;  enforcement 
of,  70-76,  see  Dependent  Stipulations, 
Independent  Stipulations,  Concurrent 
Conditions,  Special  Contracts;  discharge 
of,  77-87 ;  see  Breach,  Performance, 
Tender,  Agreement,  Novation ;  liability 
on  if  made  by  an  agent  223-224,  227- 
228;  implied  in  law,  98,  see  Quasi- 
Contract,  Implied  Contract;  persuasion 
to  break  a,  448. 

Contractual  Relations,  interference 
with,  429,  431,  448. 

Contractus  Trinus,  The,  104-105. 

Contributory  Negligence,  459-462 ; 
origin  of  doctrine  of,  459-460 ;  roughly 
pieced  on  to  mediaeval  principle  of  lia- 
bility, 460-461 ;  effect  of  this  on  the 
law,  461-462 ;  anomalous  character  of 
the  doctrine,  462 ;  compared  with  the 
Admiralty  rule,  268-269. 

Conversion,  absolute  liability  for,  466- 
468. 

Convoy,  ship  warranted  to  depart  with  a, 
292. 

Co-owners  of  Ships,  their  rights  inter 
se,  247-248;  powers  of  the  court  of 
Admiralty  in  relation  to,  248. 

CORNWAILLE,  RALPH,  102. 

Corporate  Idea,  application  of  to  com- 
mercial societies,  199,  200, 205,  215-217  ; 
application  of  to  those  societies  stopped 
by  the  Bubble  Act,  2rg-22i. 

Cotesmore,  J.,  85. 

Cottington,  Lord,  187. 

Council,  the,  its  interference  in  favour 
of  unfortunate  debtors,  233-234 ;  in  cases 
of  fraudulent  bankruptcy,  236 ;  bad  re- 
sults of  the  cessation  of  this  jurisdiction, 
244-245 ;  its  regulation  of  insurances, 
285-288. 

Covenant,  action  of,  performance  must 
be  proved  as  a  condition  of  recovery  by, 
72. 

Cranworth,  Lord,  454,  455,  468,  478. 

Creditor,  promise  to  pay  to  the  nuncius 
of  a,  115-116,  119-121. 

Crew,  rules  as  to  the  legal  position  of 
the  members  of  a,  253-254. 

Crime  and  Tort,  distinction  between 
them,  306. 


Criminal  Conversation,  the  action  for, 
43o. 

Criminal  Law,  influence  on,  of  the  Legis- 
lature, 301-302,  305  ;  of  the  Council  and 
Star  Chamber,  302  ;  of  the  common  law, 
302,  305 ;  of  the  combination  of  Star 
Chamber  and  common  law  doctrines, 
306  ;  external  influences,  306-307. 

Criminal  Offence,  actionability  of 
words  imputing  a,  347-348,  353354- 

Croke,  J.,  15,  81. 

Cromwell,  Thomas,  108. 

Culpa,  liability  grounded  on  by  the 
civilians,  258 ;  not  by  the  common 
lawyers,  259 ;  effect  on  rules  as  to 
collisions  at  sea,  266-269. 

Cunningham,  189. 

Custom,  assumpsit  for  money  due  by 
virtue  of  a,  90. 


D 


Dallas,  C.J. ,^456. 

Dalton,  329/ 

Damage,  action  for  words  causing,  350, 
358 ;  what  damage  would  give  rise  to 
the  action,  357-358;  what  was  regarded 
as  natural  and  probable,  358 ;  action  for 
malicious  statements  which  cause,  352  ; 
the  essence  of  the  tort  of  conspiracy, 
393  ;  absque  and  sine  injuria,  425,  432. 

Damages,  the.measure  of  for  negligence, 
462-464. 

Damnum  Emergens,  103. 

Dangerous  Acts,  stricter  liability  en- 
tailed by,  468 ;  mediaeval  form  of  the 
rule,  469-470;  the  modern  rule,  471- 
472. 

Darien  Company,  the,  213. 

Days  of  Grace,  156. 

De  ILeretico  Comburendo,  the  writ, 
402. 

Debray,  143. 

Debt,  a  precedent  a  consideration  for  a 
promise  to  pay,  9-10;  really  a  past 
consideration,  9,  16 ;  effect  of  this  on 
growth  of  idea  that  moral  obligation  is 
a  valid  consideration,  9,  25-26,  28,  31, 
36-37,  39-40;  how  far  payment  or  a 
promise  to  pay  the  whole  or  a  less  sum 
is  a  valid  consideration,  19-23 ;  im- 
prisonment for,  230-232 ;  defects  in 
common  law  rules  on  this  topic,  232- 
233.  245;  commissions  appointed  by 
the  Council  to  enquire  into,  234  ;  legis- 
lation as  to,  234-236. 

Debt  Action  of,  its  proprietary  nature, 
1 ;  conditions  under  which  it  lay,  3-4, 
71-72  ;  elements  in  consideration  due  to, 
3,  see  quid  pro  quo;  action  by  third 
person  to  whose  use  money  is  paid,  13  ; 
lies  to  enforce  an  executory  contract  of 


INDEX 


489 


sale,   14 ;    and    to  enforce  quasi-con- 
tractual relations,  SS. 

Deceit,  action  of,  67,  68,  426. 

Deed,  when  "  non  est  factum"  can  be! 
pleaded,  50  ;  effect  of  in  discharging  a 
contract,  80-81. 

Defamation,  333-378 ;  a  crime  and  a 
tort,  333  ;  the  division  between  libel  and 
slander,  334;  early  history,  334-335*. 
development  by  the  common  law  courts 
and  the  Star  Chamber,  335-336 ;  The 
Criminal  Offence — 336-346 ;  against  pri- 
vate persons,  336-337 ;  against  the 
government,  337;  obscene  writings,  337, 
407 ;  seditious  libels,  337-338 ;  rules  as 
to,  338-341 ;  effect  of  the  expiry  of  the 
Licensing  Act,  341 ;  the  malicious  in- 
tent, 341-342;  this  question  important 
after  the  abolition  of  the  Star  Chamber, 
342-343  ;  the  position  of  the  jury,  343- 
345  ;  beginnings  of  the  controversy  on 
this  matter,  345 ;  rudimentary  state  of 
the  law  on  many  points,  346 ;  The  Tort 
— 346-378  ;  nature  of  the  action  on  the 
case,  346-347  ;  words  actionable  per  se, 
347-350;  other  words,  350-351 ;  slander 
of  title,  351-352;  torts  analogous  thereto, 
352  ;  discouragement  of  the  action  on 
the  case,  353-355  ;  doctrine  of  "  mitior 
sensus,"  355-356  ;  liability  for  repetition 
of  a  defamatory  statement,  357  ;  rules 
as  to  the  damage  recoverable,  357-358  ; 
effect  on  the  law,  358-361 ;  origin  of 
the  distinction  between  libel  and  slander, 
361-365 ;  good  and  bad  results  on  the 
law  of  its  establishment,  365-367 ;  the 
innuendo,  368-369  ;  the  colloquium, 
369 ;  proof  that  the  statement  was  made 
of  the  plaintiff,  370-371 ;  publication, 
371 ;  the  place  of  malice,  371-375 ; 
justification,  375-376 ;  privilege,  376- 
377 ;  good  and  bad  points  of  the  law, 
378 ;  actions  for  to  question  a  decision 
that  a  man  is  a  bankrupt,  241. 

Defamatory  Words,  not  generally  a 
crime,  337. 

Delegatio,  132,  133. 

Delivery,  when  needed  to  pass  the 
property  in  a  ship,  246. 

Demurrage,  260. 

Denman,  C.J.,  34,  37,  45,  413. 

Deodand,  the,  272. 

Dependent  Promises,  73 :  failure  of 
performance  by  breach  of,  77. 

Deposit,  banks  of,  179  ;  notes,  see  Bank  \ 
Notes. 

Detinue,  action  by  person  to  whose  use 
chattels  are  conveyed,  222. 

Detrimbnt  to  Promisee,  an  essential 
element  in  consideration,  io-ii. 

Deviation,  a  breach  of  the  contract  of 
carriage,  260  ;  effect  on  the  contract  of 
insurance,  280.  291. 


Dicey,  327. 

Discharge  of  Contracts,  contracts  of, 
20-21 ;  effect  of  rise  of  executory  con- 
tracts on  rules  as  to,  22-23,  4°_4I '  by 
breach,  77-78 ;  by  performance  or 
tender,  78-80;  by  agreement,  80-85,  see 
Accord  and  Satisfaction,  Accord  Exe- 
cutory ;  by  novation,  85-87. 

Disease,  imputation  of  when  actionable, 

348-349.  354- 
Division  of  Loss,  Admiralty  rule  as  to, 

267,  268-269. 
Doctor  and   Student,  the,  5,  10,  42, 

470. 
Dodderidge,  J.,  3S7,  456. 
Dolus,  liability  based  on  by  the  civilians, 

258  ;  not  by  the  common  lawyers,  259  ; 

effect  of  this  in  collision  cases,  266- 

269. 
Domat,  43. 

D'Ouvilly,  Sir  Gerbier,  1S4. 
Drawee,  see  Acceptor. 
Drawer,  relation  to   persons  who  have 

paid  money  to  be  transported,  137, 153, 

161;  relation  to  drawee,  138,  153,  161- 

162;  relation  to  payee,  139,  153,  162- 

163. 
Drink,  implied  warranty  on  the  sale  of, 

69. 
Drunken  Persons,  contractual  capacity 

of,  52-53. 
Drunkenness,    effect    of    on    criminal 

liability,  441-443. 
Duelling,  353,  364. 
Dunbar,  Mr.,  178. 
Dunedin,  Lord,  47,  394,  396. 
Duress,  effect  of,  51 ;  remedy  for  money 

paid  by,  94. 
Dutch,  commercial  organisation  of,  184. 


Early  Law,  why  negotiable  instruments 
were  impossible  in,  115. 

East  India  Company,  194,  209,  210-21 1 ; 
becomes  a  joint  stock  company,  206. 

Eastland  Company,  199. 

Ecclesiastical  Courts,  jurisdiction  of 
over  usurers,  102 ;  over  defamation, 
335.  348. 

Ecclesiastical  Law,  part  played  by  in 
the  Middle  Ages,  402 ;  effect  of  the 
Reformation,  404  405, 406-407 ;  anomal- 
ous position  of  fc-day,  417. 

Eldon,  Lord,  317,  411. 

Eliot,  339. 

Ellenborough,  C.J.,  33. 

Employer's  Liability,  mediaeval  ideas 
as  to,  227-228,  472-473  ;  need  for  new 
rules,  228-229  *  rules  applied  by  the 
Admiralty,  249-252  ;  influence  of  these 
rules  on  the  common  law,  252-253,  475- 


490 


INDEX 


476 ;  history  of  the  doctrine  of,  472- 
479 ;  why  the  modern  doctrine  was 
introduced,  473-474  ;  Holt's  decisions, 
474-475  ;  influences  which  created  it, 
475-477  !  confusion  as  to  its  principle, 
477 ;  its  real  basis,  477-479 ;  limitations 
on  it — the  independent  contractor,  478- 
480  ;  common  employment,  480-482. 

Employes,  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade 
imposed  on,  58,  59,  61,  62. 

Enforcement  of  Contracts,  rules  as 
to,  70-76;  how  far  performance  is  a 
condition  precedent,  71 ;  rules  in  action 
of  debt,  71-72 ;  in  actions  of  covenant 
and  assumpsit,  72-73 ;  variation  of 
these  rules — independent  promises,  73  ; 
development  of  artificial  rules  of  con- 
struction, 73  ;  unsatisfac'.ory  state  of  the 
law,  73-74 ;  mutual  premises  and  con- 
current conditions,  74-75  ;  rules  applic- 
able to  indebitatus  and  special  assump- 
sit, 76 ;  action  on  a  quantum  meruit, 
76. 

Equity,  rules  of  as  to  contracts  of 
lunatics  and  drunken  persons,  53  ;  rules 
of  as  to  partners,  217-218;  as  to  lia- 
bility of  a  principal  for  his  agent's  acts, 
229. 

Equity  of  Redemption,  influence  of  the 
usury  laws,  106. 

Erle,  C.J.,  41. 

Erskine,  L.C.,  345,  443,  454- 

Erskine,  J.,  415. 

Esher,  M.R.,  397. 

Ex  Nudo  Pacto,  etc.,  30,  44. 

Exceptio    Pecunl'E    non    Numerate, 

138,  143. 

Exchangers  of  Money,  position  of  in 
England  in  sixteenth  and  seventeenth 
centuries,  126-127 !  h°w  usec*  by  mer- 
chants to  effect  the  transport  of  money, 
128-130. 

Exchequer,  the  closing  of  the,  186,  187. 

Executed  Consideration,  13 ;  how 
different  from  past  consideration,  14- 
15  ;  services  done  at  request,  15 ;  re- 
garded as  exception  to  invalidity  of 
past  consideration,  16-17;  extension  of 
this  idea,  25-26,  31-33  ;  settlement  of  the 
modern  doctrine,  37,  38-40. 

Execution,  process  of  for  debt,  primitive 
ideas,  229 ;  history  of,  230-232 ;  in- 
adequacy of  the  law,  232-233. 

Executory  Consideration,  13-14. 

Eyre,  C.J.,  479. 

Eyre,  J.,  474. 


Factors,  how  distinguished  from  brokers, 
225-226;  position  of,  226227;  mer- 
chants, liable  for  fraud  of  their,  475. 


Failure    of    Performance,  breach  of 

contract  by,  77-78. 
I  Fair  Courts,  treatment  in  of  instruments 
payable  to  bearer  or  attorney,  147 ;  of 
commercial  agency,  223. 

Fairs,   accounts   of   trading  centres  of 
Europe  adjusted  at,  179. 
'  False  Imprisonment,  388,  423  ;  action 
of  to  question  finding  that  a  man  is  a 
bankrupt,  241. 

Fathers,  inadequate  protection  of  their 
rights  to  their  children,  427-429. 

Fenner,  J.,  24. 

Feoffee  to  Uses,  222. 

Ferrara,  177. 

Fieri  Facias,  writ  of,  230. 

Finlay,  Lord,  416,  418. 

Fire,  insurance  against,  294  ;  liability  for 
damage  by,  469,  474,  476. 

Firm,  see  Partership. 

Fitzherbert,  53,  69,  424. 

Fleming,  C.J.,  228. 

Fleta,  50. 

Florence,  early  insurance  contracts  in, 
276  ;  insurance  legislation  in,  281. 

Food,  implied  warranty  on  sale  of,  69. 

Ford,  Sir  R.,  187. 

Forestallers,  57. 

Forms  of  Action,  effect  on  law  of  tort 
of  its  development  through  the,  431- 
432. 

Foster,  314,  316,  317,  320,  436. 

Fox's  Libel  Act,  374. 

Franciscans,  the,  106. 

Frankfort,  the  bank  of,  181. 

Fraud,  how  remedied  in  the  Middle 
Ages,  67-68  ;  application  of  law  as  to, 
to  contracts  of  sale  of  goods,  63- 
69 ;  law  too  narrow,  69 ;  the  idea  of 
warranty,  69-70;  development  of  the 
law,  70,  77 ;  its  effect  on  a  contract,  78  ; 
payments  induced  by,  94. 

Frauds,  Statute  of,  effect  on  contracts 
of  non-compliance  with,  65,  66 ;  in- 
direct effect  on  doctrine  of  considera- 
tion, 35-36. 

Fraudulent  Bankruptcy,  236. 

Freedom  of  Trade,  ideas  as  to,  57,  58, 
60-61,  62;  effect  on  certain  privileges  of 
early  joint  stock  companies,  209-210. 

Freight,  the  master's  power  to  hypothe- 
cate, 249 ;  the  mother  of  wages,  253- 
254,  259,  260 ;  payment  of  where  goods 
fail  to  reach  their  destination,  259-260; 
stipulations  as   to   in  charter   parties, 

255- 

French  Law,  as  to  "cause,"  43,  44,  45  ; 
as  to  bills  of  exchange,  169. 

French  Lawyers,  influence  of  Renais- 
sance school  of  on  law  of  negotiable 
instruments,  122,  133,  143,  144. 

F"reundt,  his  theory  as  to  the  origin  of 
bills  of  exchange,  134. 


INDEX 


491 


Friendly  Society  (insurance),  the,  294. 
Fund  of  Credit,  conception  of  a,  how 

used  in  seventeenth  century,  211-212; 

exaggerated  ideas  as  to  the  powers  of, 

218-219. 


Gawdy,  J.,  24,  389. 

General  Average,  255,  263-265 ;  in 
laws  of  Oleron,  263-264 ;  based  on 
Rhodian  law,  264 ;  rirst  applied  to 
jettison,  264  ;  development  of,  264-265  ; 
how  limited,  265  ;  what  contributes  to, 
265 ;  rules  as  to  valuation  of  goods 
lost,  265 ;  lien  on  cargo  for,  265. 

Gbneral  Ships,  254. 

Genoa,  the  fairs  of,  129;  loans  raised  by, 
208 ;  the  bank  of,  208 ;  its  Officium 
Robarie,  275  ;  oldest  insurance  contract 
in  archives  of,  276  ;  centre  of  insurance 
business,  278 ;  insurance  legislation  at, 
281. 

Gbrbier,  Sir  Balthasar,  183. 

Germanic  Law,  duty  of  keeping  faith  in, 
43,  44 ;  procedure  in  how  different  from 
Roman  procedure,  122. 

Gilds,  influence  of  on  companies  and 
partnerships,  193-195,  200. 

Glanvil,  102. 

Glanville,  J.,  428. 

Goldsmiths,  exchange  business  of,  127  ; 
deposit  of  money  with,  172 ;  develop- 
ment of  banking  by,  178,  185-186 ; 
criticized  for  undertaking  this  business, 
187-188 ;  practice  of  followed  by  the 
Bank  of  England,  188-iSg. 

Good  Consideration,  5,  6;  will  not 
support  a  contract,  12  ;  "influence  of  on 
doctrine  of  consideration  in  relation  to 
contracts,  12-13. 

Gordon  Riots,  the,  320-321,  331. 

Government,  what  amounts  to  a  libel  on 
the,  340-341. 

Governmental  Powers,  contained  in 
early  charters  of  companies,  201 ; 
cease  generally  to  be  given,  209-210. 

Greek  Law,  stipulations  as  to  risk  in 
contracts  of  carriage,  274. 

Grose,  J.,  454. 


H 


Habeas  Corpus,  writ  of,  to  question  the 
legality  of  a  commitment  by  Bankruptcy 
Commissioners,  241. 

Hagenbuck,  Christopher,  183. 

Hale,  308,  309,  312,  313,  314,  317,  319, 
320,  329,  364,  408,  436,  437,  438,  440, 

441.  442,  443.  444.  44^.  464.  469- 
Hales,  J.,  304. 


Hamburg,  bank  of,  181 ;   system  of  fire 

insurance  in,  294. 
Hand  in  Hand  Society,  the,  294. 
Hardwicke,  L.C.,  28,  409,  413. 
Hawkins,  308,  326,  399,  408,  441. 
Heath,  Sir  R.,  183. 
Herne,  his  book  on  pleading,  159,  160. 
High  Commission,  the  court  of,  406-407. 
Hobart,  C.J.,  54. 
Hobbes,  382. 

HOLLES,  339. 
HOLLOWAY,  J.,  473. 

Holmes,  Mr.  Justice,  372,  472. 

IIolroyd,  J.,  374. 

Holt,  C.J.,  his  opposition  to  the  extension 
of  indebitatus  assumpsit  to  remedy 
quasi-contracts,  90-91 ;  his  views  as  to 
the  non-negotiability  of  promissory 
notes,  172-176 ;  his  decisions  on  em- 
ployers' liability,  229,  252-253,  474-475, 
477 ;  39-  93.  94.  95.  96,  146.  161,  166, 
167,  168,  191,  257,  299,  303,  316,  326, 

337,  339.  341.  344.  354.  39«,  393.  400, 
424,  426,  435,  452,  453,  469,  470,  471. 
Homicide,    303-304;     when    justifiable, 

3°4,  330-33I- 
Houghton,  John,  214. 
Hudson,  382. 

Hudson's  Bay  Company,  209,  210. 
Hull,  J.,  58. 
Husband,  protection  of  his  interest  in  his 

wife's  consortium,  430. 
Huvelin,  his  description  of  the  contract 

of  cambium,  129-130;    his  criticism  of 

theories  as  to  the  origins  of  bills  of 

exchange,  133-134 ;  138. 
Hypothec,  origin   of  certain    maritime 

liens,  271. 
Hypothecation,  of  a  ship,  the  creditor's 

rights,  246-247  ;  the  master's  power  in 

relation  to,  249. 


I 


Idiot,  see  Lunatic. 

Illegal  Act,  no  action  for  words  causing 
an,  358. 

Illegality,  effect  of  on  a  contract,  53  ; 
case  where  some  stipulations  are  illegal 
and  some  legal,  53-54 ;  stipulations  not 
clearly  illegal,  54  ;  created  by  common 
and  statute  law,  54 ;  see  Public  Policy, 
Restraint  of  Trade ;  recovery  of  money 
paid  under  a  contract  void  for,  94. 

Immorality,  no  action  for  words  imput- 
ing. 348,  357- 

Implied  Contracts,  enforced  by  as- 
sumpsit, 89-90 ;  distinguished  by  Holt 
from  quasi-contracts,  90-91 ;  confused 
with  quasi-contracts,  96,  98. 

Impossibility,  promises  absolutely  im- 
possible, 63  ;   impossible  conditions  in 


492 


INDEX 


bonds,    63 ;    legal    impossibility,    63 ; 

when   a   promise   is   absolute,    63-64 ; 

when  conditional    on  possibility,   64 ; 

created  by  one  of  the  parties,  78. 
Indebitatus   Assumpsit,   when  it  lay, 

75-76  ;  use  of  to  enforce  quasi-contracts, 

88-89,  89-96  ;  8,  16, 17. 
Indemnity,  marine  insurance  a  contract 

of,  278,  279,  290 ;    different   from  life 

and  accident  insurance,  295. 
Independent  Contractor,  employer  not 

generally  liable  for  torts  of,  479-480. 
Independent   Promises,  73;  failure  to 

perform,  77. 
Indorsees,    position   of   inter   se,    143, 

163-164;  rights  of,  141,  142-143,  163- 

164. 
Indorsement,  early  history  of,  141-143, 

163-164  ;  application  of  to  bills  of  debt, 

149;    to   bills   of  exchange,    135-136; 

transfer  by,  163  ;  notes  payable  to  order 

transferable  by,  171. 
Industry,  legal  effects  of  its  organization 

on  a  capitalistic  basis,  112-113. 
Infancy,  effect  cf  on  criminal  liability, 

438-439- 
Infant,    capacity    to    contract,    51-52 ; 

liability    to    pay   for   necessaries,   52 ; 

incapacity  to  be  made  bankrupt,  237. 
Inland  Bills,  158,  171,  175  ;  promissory 

notes  assimilated  to   by  statute,  173  ; 

Holt  saw  they  differed  from  promissory 

notes,  174. 
Innkeepers,  449,  451,  452-453  ;  duties  of 

enforced  by  action  on  the  case,  89. 
Innominate    Contract,    insurance    re- 
garded as  an,  278. 
Innuendo,  the,  368-369. 
Insanity,  effect  of  on  criminal  liability, 

439-441. 
Instalments,  payment  by,  79. 
Instrumenta  ex  Causa  Cambii,    132, 

136-137- 
Insurance,  273-298  ;  its  place  in  modern 
law,  273  ;  definition  of,  274  ;  Marine 
—  origins,  274-283  ;  Greek  and  Roman 
law — stipulations  as  to  risk,  274-275  ; 
associations  formed  to  guard  against 
risks,  275  ;  thirteenth  century  contracts 
— stipulations  as  to  risk,  275-276  ;  the 
oldest  contract  of  276-277  ;  modelled  at 
first  on  bottomry,  263,  277 ;  later  on 
sale,  277-278 ;  growth  of  insurance 
business,  278 ;  emerges  as  a  distinct 
contract,  278 ;  its  form,  279 ;  rules  re- 
lating to  it,  279-281 ;  legislation  as  to 
it,  281-283 ;  introduction  into  and  de- 
velopment in  England,  283-293  ;  earliest 
instances  on  records  of  the  court  of 
Admiralty,  283  ;  prevalence  in  sixteenth 
century,  283-284 ;  policies  follow  the  j 
continental  model,  284-285  ;  regulation  j 
by  the  Council,  285 ;   monopoly  right  ' 


to  register  insurances,  286-287 ;  tribunal 
to  try  insurance  cases,  287-288 ;  why 
not  a  succeis,  288;  the  statutory  tri- 
bunal, 289 ;  its  defects,  289-290 ;  back- 
ward state  of  the  law,  290,  293  ;  rules 
evolved  by  the  Admiralty,  290-291 ;  by 
the  courts  of  common  law,  291-292 ; 
defects  of  common  law  procedure,  292- 
293  ;  Other  Forms,  294-298 ;  against 
risks  of  land  transport,  294;  against 
fire,  294;  accident  and  life,  295-296; 
against  certain  risks  to  the  person,  296  ; 
these  insurances  did  not  develop,  296- 
297  ;  known  in  England,  297  ;  instances 
of  life  policies  and  insurances  against 
personal  risks,  297-298  ;  premiums  for 
not  obnoxious  to  the  usury  laws,  104  ; 
disguised  under  other  forms  to  evade 
these  laws,  106. 

Insurance  Policies,  considered  by  the 
merchants  to  be  as  negotiable  as  bills 
of  exchange,  175. 

Insured,  origin  of  the  rule  that  he  must 
have  an  interest,  278,  292. 

Insurer,  why  the  goo^s  were  at  his  risk 
and  he  could  sue  for  them  during  the 
voyage,  277 ;  why  entitled  to  any 
property  recovered,  278,  290 ;  clauses 
binding  him  to  pay  though  the  insured 
had  no  interest,  279-280 ;  liability  in 
case  of  capture  and  rescue,  280,  291- 
292. 

Insuring  Safety,  the  duty  of,  468-470  ; 
how  far  the  master  of  a  ship  is  under 
this  duty  to  merchants  and  passengers, 
251;  and  in  respect  of  the  goods 
carried,  258-259. 

Intent,  malicious,  how  far  needed  in 
libel,  342-345.  371-375 ;  in  conspiracy, 
396 ;  without  an  overt  act  is  not  criminal, 

433-434- 
Intention  to  Libel,  when  imputed,  370- 

37i. 

Intention,  wrongful,  when  need  to 
ground  civil  liability,  447-448. 

Invalidity  of  Contract,  49-70  ;  absence 
of  consent,  50-51;  duress,  51;  undue 
influence,  51 ;  incapacity  of  parties, 
51-55,  see  Infants,  Married  Women, 
Drunken  Persons,  Lunatics;  illegality, 
53 ;  severance  of  legal  from  illegal 
stipulations,  53-54;  stipulations  net 
clearly  illegal,  54 ;  illegality  by  common 
and  statute  law,  54;  public  policy,  54- 
56;  restraint  of  trade,  56-62;  impossi- 
bility, 62-64;  alteration  cf  contract 
under  seal,  64;  statutory  provisions, 
65  ;  void,  voidable,  and  unenforceable, 
65-66 ;  why  these  distinctions  have  been 
obscured,  67 ;  fraud  and  misrepresenta- 
tion, 67-70,  see  Fraud,  Misrepresenta- 
tion, Warranty. 

Issue,  banks  of,  179. 


INDEX 


493 


Italian  States,  money  borrowed  by, 
106 ;  legislation  as  to  banking  in,  1S0- 
181. 


J 


Jeffreys,  L.C.,  341. 

Jenks,  h6. 

Jessel,  M.R.,  56. 

Jesuits,  legislation  as  to,  412. 

Jettison,  consultation  with  crew  before 
a,  253,  264. 

Jews,  business  as  financiers,  177;  legis- 
lation as  to,  413. 

Joint  Estate,  of  a  fnm,  how  ad- 
ministered in  bankruptcy,  242-243. 

Joint  Stock  Companies,  see  Companies. 

Jones,  J.,  15. 

Joyce,  J.,  417. 

Judgment,  action  of  debt  on  a,  98; 
remedy  for  money  paid  under  a  void, 

94. 

Judicium  rusticum,  268. 

Jury,  functions  in  trials  for  libel,  343- 

345  ;  in  actions  for  libel,  373-375- 
Jus  accrescendi    inter    mercatores, 

etc.,  217. 
Justification,  the  plea  of,  375-376. 


K 


Kenny,  Professor,  306, 321,  331,  381, 436, 

44°,  445- 
Kenyon,  C.J.,  76. 
King's  Bench,  jurisdiction  of  as  censor 

morum,  407-408. 


Laissez   Faire,   school    of   economists, 

101 ;  effect  of  on  law  of  tort,  431. 
Lamb,  S.,  his  '  Seasonable  Observations,' 

184,  189. 
Land,  liability  for  trespass  on,  466-468. 
Land  Law,  commercial  law  becomes  a 

rival  to,  299. 
Larceny,  304 ;  the  mens  rea  in,  437. 
Lattes,  177. 

Law,  John,  212  ;  his  bank,  125. 
Law    Merchant,   founded    on    foreign 

doctrines,    99  ;     chat  acteris tics    of    in 

England,  298-299;   its  effects   on   the 

common  law,  299-300. 
Lawrence,  J.,  461. 
Leases,  grants  of  to  evade  prohibition  of 

usury,  105. 
Lechmere,  B.,  86. 
Lee,  Professor,  44. 
Lefort,  274. 
Letters  of  Credit,  154. 
Letters  Patent  and  Close,  suggested 

origin  of  bills  of  exchange,  134-136. 


Letters  of  Payment,  132,  136-137. 

Levant  Company,  The,  209. 

Levari  Facias,  the  writ  of,  230. 

Leviations,  made  on  shareholders  by  the 
company,  204. 

Liabilities,  a  bankrupt's,  not  discharged 
by  the  bankruptcy,  240,  243. 

Liability,  the  principles  of,  433-482; 
Criminal — 433-446 ;  mens  rea,  433-43S  ; 
infancy,  438-439 ;  insanity,  439-441 ; 
drunkenness,  441-443 ;  coercion,  443- 
444 ;  compulsion,  444-445  ;  necessity, 
445  ;  Civil — 446-482 ;  the  mediaeval 
principle  and  its  modifications,  446-447  ; 
wrongful  intent,  447-44S ;  negligence — 
unknown  in  the  Middle  Ages,  449-450 ; 
introduction  into  the  common  law,  450- 
452 ;  its  application  to  bailees,  452-453  ; 
to  persons  not  contractually  related  to 
the  plaintiff,  453  ;  difficulty  in  applying 
it  to  trespass,  453-455 ;  how  it  was 
applied,  455-458 ;  contributory  negli- 
gence, 459-462 ;  measure  of  damages 
lor  negligence,  462-464;  liability  for 
wrongs  to  property,  465-468 ;  cases 
falling  under  the  Fletcher  v.  Ry land's 
rule,  468-472  ;  see  Employers'  Liability, 
Independent  Contractor,  Common  Em- 
ployment. 

Libel,  see  Defamation ;  origin  of  distinc- 
tion from  slander,  361-365. 

Licensin  j  Act,  The,  338,  340,  341. 

Lien,  of  lenders  on  bottomry,  262 ;  see 
Maritime  Litns. 

Life  Insurance,  character  of,  295 ; 
hardly  known  in  this  period,  295-296 ; 
beginnings  of  in  hngland, '297-298. 

Limitation,  statutes  of,  promise  to  pay 
a  debt  barred  by,  26,  27,  31,  37,  39,  40 ; 
their  effect  on  contracts,  65,  66. 

Limited  Liability,  204-205. 

Limited  Partnership,  196-197. 

Lindley,  Lord,  397,  463. 

Litigation,  statements  made  in  course 
of  privileged,  376. 

Littleton,  Edward,  409. 

Lloyd's  Coffee  House,  293. 

Loans,  insurance  contracts  disguised  as, 
275-276;  see  Usury. 

Loans  to  the  State,  connection  of  with 
the  history  of  banking,  179,  181,  18S, 
189 ;  influence  of  on  growth  of  joint 
stock  principle,  207-208. 

Lombard  Lawyers,  circumvention  by  of 
the  rule  that  choses  in  action  are  not  as- 
signable, 115-119. 

London,  ordinances  as  to  usury,  102, 
104 ;  regulation  of  brokers  in,  224 ; 
Mayor's  Court,  thirteenth-century  cases 
as  to  bills  of  exchange,  130- 131,  132, 
146,  152. 

London  Corresponding  Society,  The, 
318. 


494 


INDEX 


Lorenzen,  Professor,  47. 

Lost  Bill,  liability  on  a,  156. 

Lucrum  cessans,  103. 

Lunatics,   contractual   capacity   of,  52- 

53- 
Lushington,  Sir  Godfrey,  394. 
Luther,  his  views  on  usury,  109. 
Lyons,  the  lairs  of,  129. 


M 


Macauley,  Lord,  214. 

Madox,  147. 

Maintenance,  397-402  ;  why  it  assumed 
its  modern  form,  398 ;  its  criminal 
aspect  tends  to  disappear,  398-399 ; 
essential  features  of,  399 ;  how  far  the 
rules  of  the  tort  and  the  crime  are  the 
same,  399-400;  need  to  prove  damage, 
400-401 ;  effect  of  the  success  of  the 
maintained  litigation,  401-402 ;  effect 
on  development  of  law  of,  of  the  aboli- 
tion of  the  Star  Chamber,  361-364. 

Maitland,  223. 

Malice,  how  far  essential  in  libel,  341- 
345,  371-375  ;  legal  and  actual,  374. 

Malice  Aforethought,  435-436. 

Malicious  Prosecution,  385-391 ;  the 
mediaeval  remedies,  385  ;  comparison  of 
the  statutory  writ  for  with  the  action  on 
the  case,  385-386  ;  conspiracies  to  indict 
for  treason,  386-387  ;  for  misdemeanour, 
387  ;  need  for  acquittal,  388-389  ;  elimi- 
nation of  the  element  of  conspiracy, 
389-390 ;  restatement  of  the  law  by 
Holt,  390-391 ;  relation  to  false  im- 
prisonment, 388. 

Malicious  Statements,  action  for,  352. 

Malynes,  his  views  as  to  the  usury  laws, 
no,  in;  his  description  of  a  public 
bank,  182-183 ;  opposes  the  establish- 
ment of  such  a  bank  in  England,  187  ; 
information  as  to  brokers,  224 ;  as  to 
factors,  226 ;  account  of  Italian  bank- 
ruptcy laws,  230;  of  the  commissioners 
in  bankruptcy,  238  ;  of  bills  of  lading, 
256  ;  as  to  freight  on  goods  saved  from 
wreck,  260 ;  as  to  insurances  against 
personal  risks,  297-298  ;  127,  148,  149, 
150,  152,  153,  154.  155.  167,  251,  252, 
254,  255,  261,  288,  293. 

Manning,  Serjeant,  429. 

Manorial  Courts,  jurisdiction  of  in 
cases  of  defamation,  335. 

Mansfield,  Lord,  his  views  on  considera- 
tion, 25,  26-31  ;  their  rejection,  35-38 ; 
effect  of  this,  34,  38-42, 46-47  ;  his  views 
were  an  intelligent  anticipation  of  the 
future,  47-48  ;  his  contribution  to  the 
law  of  quasi-contract,  97  ;  168, 171,  293, 
320,  344,  414,  445,  453. 

Mansfield,  C.J.,  33,  36,  365,  366. 


Manslaughter,  303  ;   the  mens  rea  in, 

436-437- 

Manwood,  C.B.,  7. 

March,  355. 

Maritime  Law,  245-273 ;  see  Ships, 
Master,  Crew,  Carriage,  Bills  of  Lad- 
ing, Bottomry,  General  Average,  Col- 
lision, Salvage,  Maritime  Liens. 

Maritime  Liens,  270-273  ;  definition  of, 
270 ;  how  they  arise,  270-271 ;  com- 
pared with  common  law  liens,  271  ; 
origins,  271-273. 

Marius,  his  information  as  to  bills  of 
exchange,  155-157- 

Markby,  his  criticisms  of  the  doctrine  of 
consideration,  46. 

Marowe,  326,  434. 

Marquahdus,  his  views  on  usury,  in  ; 
on  banking,  182  ;  142,  181. 

Married  Women,  their  contractual  in- 
capacity, 51. 

Marsden,  268,  272. 

Martin,  B.,  31. 

Master,  liability  of  for  servant's  acts, 
see  Employers'  Liability. 

Master,  The,  of  a  ship,  powers  of,  248- 
249  ;  comparison  with  the  common  law 
rules  of  agency,  249-250 ;  liability  to 
passengers  and  merchants  for  the  torts 
of  the  crew,  250-251 ;  liability  of  owner 
for  his  torts,  251-252  ;  effect  of  these 
doctrines  on  the  common  law,  252-253  ; 
relation  to  the  crew,  253-254. 

Master  and  Servant,  see  Principal  and 
Agent. 

Master's  Mate,  The,  248. 

McCardie,  J.,  395,  456. 

Melancthon,  views  as  to  usury,  log. 

Mens  Rea,  the  basis  of  criminal  liability, 
433-435  !  its  nature  in  different  crimes, 
435-437  !  see  Infancy,  Insanity,  Drunk- 
enness. 

Mercantile  Law,  Lord  Mansfield's  use 
of  the  doctrines  of,  29-30. 

Merchant  Adventurers,  The,  199. 

Merchants,  their  legal  relation  to  ship- 
owners, 258-260 ;  their  regulation  of 
insurances,  285. 

Merchants  of  Andalusia,  Company  of, 
200. 

Mesne  Process,  231. 

Middleburg,  bank  of,  181. 

Mineral  and  Battery  Works,  the 
society  of,  208,  216. 

Mines  Royal,  the  company  of,  194,  208, 
216. 

Ministerial  Responsibility,  443. 

MlSADVENTUREK304. 

Misdemeanours,  growth  of,  301-302, 
305  ;  conspiracies  to  indict  for,  387. 

Misprision,  322-323  ;  of  treason,  323-324  ; 
statutory  offence  of,  324 ;  of  felony, 
323. 


INDEX 


495 


land,  149-152 ;  origins  of  bills  of  ex- 
change— abroad,  126-146,  in  England, 
mercantile  practice,  152-159,  English 
law  as  to,  159-170,  see  Bills  of  Ex- 
change; promissory  notes,  170-176;  see 
Negotiability,  Promissory  Notes;  the 
gift  of  a  for  a  lesser  sum  than  that  due 
under  a  contract  a  good  discharge,  85  ; 
why  bills  of  lading  are  not,  257. 
Negotiability,  the  essentials  of,  1 13-114  ; 
the  juridical  bases  of,  145-146;  why 
impossible  in  early  law,  115;  partial 
removal  of  these  difficulties — abroad, 
115-119,  in  England,  147-151;  develop- 
ment of  these  devices,  120-124;  wny 
they  failed  to  develop  the  modern 
qualities  of,  124-125,  150-151,  170-172 ; 
development  of  in  connection  with  bills 
of  exchange — abroad,  140-145,  in  Eng- 
land, 157-158,  163-168  ;  effect  of  the 
statute  as  to  promissory  notes,  176. 
distinguished  from  consideration,  I  Nevil,  J.,  86. 

New  England  Company,  the,  209. 


Misrepresentation,  originally  no  reme- 
dy for  non-fraudulent,  67,  68;  law 
developed  through  the  rules  as  to  im- 
plied warranties,  69-70,  78. 

Missibilia,  116. 

Mistake,  remedy  for  money  paid  by,  94. 

Mitior  Sensus,  The,  335,  355-356,  366. 

Molloy,  226. 

Monarchy,  a  public  bank  said  to  be 
incompatible  with,  186-187. 

Money  Changers,  The,  the  earliest 
bankers,  177,  178. 

Monopoly,  illegality  of,  60 ;  contracts 
creating  a,  61. 

MONTES  PlETATIS,  Io6,  l8o. 

Moral  Obligation,  confusion  with  con- 
sideration, 3,  17 ;  Mansfield's  use  of 
this  idea,  26-29 ;  prevalence  of  his 
views,  30-33 ;  their  rejection,  36-38  ; 
effects  of  this,  34,  45. 

Motive,  confused  with  consideration,  32 
33i 
38. 

Murder,  303-304  ;  the  mens  rea  in,  435- 
436. 

Mutual   Promises,  a  consideration  for 


New  Mills  Company,  the,  206. 
New  River  Company,  the,  202. 
Newcome,  Thomas,  184. 
Non  est  factum,  plea  of,  65-66. 


Non- 


each  other,  g. 
Mutuum,  evasion  of  its  gratuitous  char- 1  Non-conformity,    see    Religious 
acter  by  stipulations  as  to  risk,  275.  conformity. 

!  North,  L.K.,  25,  242. 
Notaries,  why  employed   to   draw    up 


N 


National  Debt,  The,  135-136. 
National  Debts,  taken  over  by  banks  in 

Italy,    181 ;    this  is  the  origin  of  the 

Bank  of  England,  188. 
Natural  Law,  Lord  Mansfield's  appeals  j  Noxal  Liability,  272 

to,  27;    theory  that  it  demanded  the  j  Nude  Pacts,  29,  30,  42. 


insurance  contracts,  279. 
Novatio  the,  132,  133. 
Novation,   not  possible    in  the   Middle 

Ages,  85-86  ;  when  it  became  possible, 

86 ;  development  of  the  law  as  to,  86- 

87. 


Nuisance,  what  is  a,  425-426 ;  public — 
when  redressible  by  an  action  in  tort, 
363,  424-425 ;  liability  for,  471. 

Nuncius,  promise  to  pay  to  a  creditor  or 
a,  116-118,  119-121. 


enforceability  of  agreements,  36,  43 
Necessaries,    nature    of    the     infant's 

liability  for,  52. 
Necessity,    how    far    a    defence   to    a 

criminal  charge,  445 ;  how  far  a  defence 

to  an  action  for  trespass,  455-456,  458. 
Negligence,  unknown  in  mediaeval  law, 

449-450 ;  how  introduced  into  English 

law,   450-451;    application  of  to  con- 
tractual and  quasi-contractual  relations, 

451-452;  to  bailees,  452-453  ;  to  other   Obscene  Writings,  333,  337. 

relations,    453  ;    to   trespass,   453-458  ;    Office,  action  for  imputation  of  unfitness 

measure  of  damages  for,  see  Damages ;  \     for,  349-350,  355. 

effect  of  in  executing  a  deed,  50-51 ;  see  |  Office    of  Assurances,   286-287,   289, 

Contributory  Negligence.  289-290,  293. 

Negotiable  Instruments,  bills  of  ex-  j  Officium  Roba^ie,  275. 

change  the  earliest  form  of,  114  ;  origins  1  Oleron,  the  laws  of,  253,  260,  263. 

— early  documents  promising  payment j  Original   Contract,   use   made  of    by 

to  creditor's   nominee  or   producer  off      Blackstone   to    explain    the    scope    of 

document,     115-119;    development    of;      indebitatus  assumpsit,  96. 

law  as  to  these  documents — abroad,  119- j  Outland  Bills,  158,  171. 

124,  in  England,  147-149  ;  loss  of  their   Overt  Acts,  proving  treason,  309,  311, 

negotiable  character,  124-125;  shifts  of       312,  314,  315,  316,  327-328;  needed  to 

the  merchants — abroad,  125-126,  in  Eng-       expose  to  criminal  liability,  433. 


496 


INDEX 


Owner  of  a  Ship,  liability  on  the  master's 
contracts,  249-250;  for  torts  of  the 
master  and  crew,  250,  251-252. 


Parette,  Stephan,  183. 

Park,  263. 

Parke,  B.,  33,  37,  55,  461. 

Parker,  C.J.  and  L.C.,   27,  60,  62,  74, 

374,  389.  391- 
Parker,  Lord,  418. 
Parlement  of  Paris,  decrees  of  as  to 

instruments  drawn  payable  to  bearer  or 

in  blank,  125-126. 
Parliamentary     Proceedings,     state 

ments  made  in   course  of   privileged, 

376. 
Partners,  agents  for  each   other,  217; 

joint  and  separate  estate  of,  217,  242- 

243- 

Partnership,  primitive  and  non  com- 
mercial, 195 ;  mediaeval  and  com- 
mercial, 195-199;  firm  not  a  distinct 
person,  198 ;  large  partnerships  become 
companies,  208-209;  not  clearly  dis- 
tinguished from  a  company,  215 ;  no 
survivorship,  217 ;  other  rules  applicable 
to,  217  218;  beginnings  of  equitable 
jurisdiction  as  to,  217-218 ;  see  Com- 
mcnda,  Socictas,  Limited  Partnership. 

Passengers,  248,  250. 

Past  Consideration,  not  valid,  14;  dis- 
tinguished from  executed  consideration, 
14-15  ;  confusion  between  them  caused 
by  method  of  statement,  15 ;  services 
done  on  request  a  valid  consideration, 
16-17  5  extension  of  this  idea,  25-26, 
31-33  ;  settlement  of  modern  doctrine, 
37.  38-40- 

Payee,  of  a  bill  of  exchange,  relation  to 
acceptor,  138-139,  162;  relation  to 
drawer,  139-140,  162-163 ;  position  of, 
140. 

Payment,  rules  as  to,  79 ;  remedy  when 
money  was  not  due,  94 ;  by  cheque  or 
bank  note,  191-192. 

Pecunia  Trajectitia,  relation  of  to 
bottomry,  261-262  ;  relation  to  the  con- 
tract of  insurance,  275. 

Pepys,  187. 

Performance,  of  a  contract,  how  far  a 
consideration  for  a  promise  by  a  third 
person,  23-24,  41 ;  in  discharge  of  a 
contract,  78-79. 

Periam,  J.  and  C.B.,  15. 

Perils  of  the  Sea,  291. 

Permutatio,  126. 

Personal  Risks,  early  insurances  against, 
296 ;  their  prohibition,  296  ;  disguised 
as  sales,  296-297 ;  known  in  England, 
297-298. 


Peruzzi,  The,  178,  207. 

Petilodeminage,  255. 

Phillimore,  Lord,  401. 

Pilotage,  255. 

Pleading,  Rules  of  1834;   tneir  effect 

on  the  settlement  of  doctrine  of  con- 
sideration, 38. 
Plowden,  303. 
Police  System,  effect  of  inadequacy  of 

on  criminal  law,  331-332. 
Policies,  benefits  of   assignable,   291 ; 

modelled    on   Italian  forms,   284-285 ; 

see  Insurance  Policies. 
Policy,  origin  of  the  word  as  applied  to 

insurance,  277. 
Pollock,  C.B.,  37. 
Pollock,  Sir  F.,  34,  39,  46,  66,  335,  354, 

358,  395,  428,  45°,  467,  468,  479- 

POPHAM,  C.J.,  252. 

Post-Glossators,  The,  133. 

POTHIER,  43. 

Powell,  J.,  86. 
Powys,  B.,  86. 

Premium,   in  insurance  contracts,   275, 
276,  277;  when  recoverable,  281,  292. 
Presentment  for  Acceptance,  156. 
Press,  rules  as  to  the  licensing  of  the, 

338,  34i- 
Presumptions,  in  favour  of  the  payee  of 

a  bill  of  exchange,  143-144,  165-167. 
Primage,  255. 
Principal  and  Agent,  why  classed  as 

part  of  the  law  of  Master  and  Servant, 

227 ;   see  Agency. 
Prisoners  for  Debt,  legislation  as  to, 

234-236. 
Privilege,  the  defence  of,  372,  375,  376- 

377- 

Process,  malicious  abuse  of,  388. 

Procurator,  in  rem  suam,  132. 

Producer,  of  a  document,  promises  to 
pay  the,  116,  121-124. 

Profession,  action  for  imputation  of 
unfitness  for,  349,  355. 

Promissory  Notes,  early  continental 
documents,  115-119;  loss  of  their 
negotiable  characteristics,  119-126; 
similar  documents  in  England,  147- 
151;  tendency  to  assimilate  them  to 
bills  of  exchange,  170-172;  stopped  by 
Holt's  decisions,  172-173  ;  reasons  for 
them,  173-176;  declared  by  statute  to 
be  negotiable,  176 ;  the  effects  of  this 
controversy,  176,  299-300. 

Promoters  of  companies,  214-215. 

Prosecution,  forbearance  to,  how  far  a 
consideration,  18-19;  malicious,  see 
Malicious  Prosecution. 

Protest,  of  a  bill  of  exchange,  rules  as 
to,  138,  156,  171,  174. 

Public  Policy,  relation  to  law  of  con- 
tract, 54-56  ;  legitimate  and  illegitimate 
use  of  the  conception  of,  383 ;  analo- 


INDEX 


497 


gous  use  of  the  concept  of  conspiracy, 
384  ;  the  justification  of  the  doctrine  of 
employers'  liability,  250,  252-253,  478- 

479- 
Publication,  in  relation  to  defamation, 

339,  357.  37i. 


Quakers,  411. 

Qualified  Privilege,  377. 

Quantum  Meruit,  assumpsit  on  a,  52 ; 
when  an  action  on  will  lie,  76. 

Quasi  Contract,  how  shaped  by  medi- 
aeval actions  of  debt  and  account,  88  ; 
developed  by  indebitatus  assumpsit, 
88-89 ;  origins  of  the  modern  law,  89, 
97-98  ;  growth  of  sphere  of  indebitatus 
assumpsit,  8g-g2;  Holt's  opposition, 
go-91 ;  extension  to  remedy  cases  of 
unjust  enrichment,  93-94 ;  payments 
when  money  is  not  due,  94 ;  wrongful 
taking  of  money,  94-96  ;  confusion  of 
the  law  in  Blackstone's  day,  96  ;  Lord 
Mansfield's  contribution  to  the  modern 
law,  96  97  ;  infant's  liability  to  pay  for 
necessaries  is  based  on,  52. 

Quasi-delicts,  Roman  law  as  to,  250, 
252. 

Quasi-torts,  why  no  such  category  is 
recognized  in  English  law,  89. 

Quid  Pro  Quo,  acquires  technical  mean- 
ing in  relation  to  action  of  debt,  4,  6 ; 
analogies  from,  influences  doctrine  of 
consideration,  7 ;  origin  of  idea  that 
benefit  to  promisor  is  an  essential 
element  in  consideration,  10-11,  13 ; 
agreement  a  sufficient  in  the  case  of 
sale  of  goods,  14 ;  payment  of  less  than 
is  due  is  not  a  sufficient  for  a  release, 
20 ;  doing  another  act  may  be,  21-22 ; 
French  analogies,  43  ;  influence  of  on 
rules  as  to  the  enforcement  of  contracts, 
71-72. 


K 


Rafael  de  Turri,  142. 

Rastell's  Entries,  159. 

Ratification,  233. 

Raymond,  Lord,  91,  344,  345,  408. 

Reasonableness,  the  test  of  the  validity 

of  contracts  in  restraint  of  trade,  59,  60, 

61,  62. 
Reassurance,  291. 
Rede,  J.,  465. 
Reformation,  character  of  the  English, 

403. 
Refusal  to  perform  a  contract,  78. 
Registration  of  Insurances,  monopoly 

right  of,  286-287. 


Regrators,  57. 

Regulated  Companies,  see  Companies. 

Religious  Noncomformity,  legal  doc- 
trines resulting  from  laws  against,  402- 
420;  summary  of  development  of  the 
law,  402-405 ;  law  of  the  seventeenth 
and  eighteenth  ceuturies,  406-410;  re- 
peal of  legislation  against,  410-414 ; 
effect  of  this  on  legal  doctrine,  414-417  ; 
effect  of  new  doctrine  on  the  interpreta- 
tion of  older  legislation,  417-418  ;  trend 
of  the  law,  418-419;  its  future,  419- 
420. 

Religious  Orders,  legislation  as  to,  412, 
417. 

Rent  Charges,  creation  of  to  evade 
usury  laws,  105. 

Repetition   of  a  slander,  liability   for, 

357- 

Representation,  originally  not  allowed 
in  litigation,  115;  how  this  prohibition 
was  evaded,  116-117. 

Reputed  Ownership,  rule  as  to  in 
bankruptcy,  240. 

Respondentia,  see  Bottomry. 

Restraint  of  Princes,  291. 

Restraint  of  Trade,  56-62,  see  Trade. 

Revolution  (1688),  promotes  greater 
freedom  of  trade,  59-60. 

Rhodes,  J.,  15. 

Rhodian  Law,  the,  264. 

Riot,  how  distinguished  from  a  levying 
of  war,  319-321,  322,  328 ;  Brooke's 
definition  of,  324  ;  nature  of  the  offence, 
325 ;  sixteenth  century  legislation  as 
to,  327 ;  liability  of  rioters,  329-330 ; 
duties  of  citizens  in  regard  to,  330-331 ; 
see  Riot  Act. 

Riot  Act,  the,  320,  328-329,  330,  331. 

Rioters,  liability  of,  329-330. 

Risks,  specified  in  contracts  of  insurance, 
280. 

Robbery,  304. 

Rokeby,  J.,  91,  425. 

Rolf,  85. 

Rolle,  C.J.,  13,  72,  297,  355,  372,  428, 
429. 

Roman  Catholics,  plots  of,  effect  on  law 
of  treason,  310  ;  legislation  as  to,  411, 
412. 

Roman  Law,  as  to  nude  pacts,  3 ;  as  to 
discharge  of  contracts,  20-21,  80;  as 
to  causa,  42,  43 ;  as  to  contracts  of 
lunatics,  53  ;  as  to  novation,  85  ;  as  to 
symbolical  delivery,  118 ;  influence  on 
older  instruments  payable  to  order  or 
bearer,  121  124  ;  procedure  of  compared 
with  Germanic  procedure,  122 ;  bills 
of  exchange  not  known  to,  132-133  ; 
influence  of  rules  as  to  quasi-delicts  on 
maritime  law,  250,  252;  stipulations  as 
to  risk  in,  in  contracts  of  carriage,  274- 
275;   as  to  defamation,   333-334,  366; 


VOL.  VIII.— 32 


498 


INDEX 


contributory  negligence  in,  459  ;  influ- 
ence   of   on    doctrine    of    employers' 
liability,  475-476. 
Roman-Dutch   Law,  causa   in,   43,  44, 

45- 
Romilly,  Lord,  417. 
Rotterdam,  bank  of,  181. 
Rout,  definition  of  a,  324. 
Royal  African  Company,  the,  209. 
Russia  Company,  the,  209,  210. 


St.  George,  bank  of,  181. 

St.  Germain,  5,  14. 

Sale,  contract  of  enforced  by  action  of 
debt,  14 ;  insurance  contracts  disguised 
as  a,  275-276,  277 ;  effects  of  this,  277- 
278. 

Sale  of  Goods,  warranties  in  connection 
with,  68-69,  7° !  growth  of  idea  of  fraud 
in  connection  with,  68-6g ;  no  need  to 
show  performance  to  recover  on  a  con- 
tract for,  72. 

Salman,  the,  222. 

Salvage,  269-270  ;  actions  for,  270. 

Salvors,  rights  of  in  the  court  of  Admir- 
alty, 269-270 ;  at  common  law,  270. 

Scaccia,  136,  142,  143,  198. 

scandalum  magnatum,  335,  34o,  376. 

SCHUTE,  J.,  389. 

Scienter    Rule,    the,    451,    457,    465, 

469. 
Scotch   Law,   English   law  of  contract 

might  have  been  assimilated  to  if  Lord 

Mansfield's  views  had   prevailed,   34 ; 

the  firm  a  legal  person  in,  198. 
Scott,  Dr.,  193,  211,  213,  221. 

SCRIPTA  OBLIGATORIA,  Il6. 

Scriveners,  connection  of  with  banking 

business,  185. 
Scroggs,  C.J.,  12,  340,  343. 

SCRUTTON,  L.J.,  395. 

Seal,  contract  under,  effect  of  in  discharg- 
ing a  contract,  80-81 ;  bills  of  exchange 
said  to  be  in  the  nature  of,  168,  175. 

Sedition,  relation  of  to  religious  non- 
conformity, 407,  408-409,  419-420. 

Seditious  Words,  339-340. 

Seditious  Writings,  333,  338-341 ;  the 
seditious  intent,  341-342 ;  functions  of 
the  jury  in  relation  to,  342-345. 

Seduction,  the  remedy  for,  428-429. 

Selborne,  L.C.,  40. 

Self  Defence,  304. 

Selwyn,  32. 

Separate  Estate  of  a  firm,  administra- 
tion of  in  bankruptcy,  242-243. 

Servants,  threatened  violence  to,  423 ; 
remedy  for  abduction  of,  429. 

Severance  of  legal  from  illegal  stipula- 
tions in  a  contract,  53-54. 


Shareholders,  liability  to  creditors,  203- 
204 ;  to  the  company,  204 ;  limitation 
of  their  liability,  204-205. 

Shares,  transferable,  203,  207,  208,  220, 
221 ;  dealings  in,  214 ;  misdeeds  of 
dealers  in,  214. 

Shaw,  C.J.,  478,  481. 

Sheriffs,  liability  of  for  acts  of  their 
subordinates,  474,  475,  477. 

Ship,  presumption  of  the  loss  of  a,  280, 
291. 

Ship's  Boy,  the,  248. 

Ship's  Register,  255. 

Shipowners,  liability  to  merchants,  258  ; 
how  far  insurers,  258-259 ;  right  to 
freight,  259-260  ;  right  to  have  a  cargo 
provided,  260;  right  to  withhold  de- 
livery till  payment  of  freight,  260. 

Ships,  modes  of  acquisition,  246;  de- 
claration of  title  to,  246  ;  liens  on,  246- 
247 ;  co-ownership  of,  247  ;  disputes 
between  co-owners,  247-248  ;  arrest  of, 
247  ;  process  of  arrest  and  maritime 
liens,  272-273,  see  Maritime  Liens. 

Shipwright,  The,  248. 

Shower,  Sir  Bartholomew,  91,  257. 

Si  actio,  when  a  proper  mode  of  pleading, 
65-66. 

Simple  Contract,  operation  of  in  dis- 
charging a  contract,  81-85  5  no  effect  on 
a  contract  under  seal,  81 ;  modification 
of  this  rule,  82  ;  executed  and  executory 
contracts,  82-83  ;  see  Accord  and  Satis- 
faction. 

Skynner,  C.B.,  36. 

Slander,  see  Defamation ;  origin  of,  dis- 
tinction from  libel,  361-365. 

Slander  of  Title,  351-352. 

Smith,  Adam,  180. 

Smiths,  449,  451. 

Societas,  the,  how  it  differed  from 
Commenda,  197  ;  relation  of  the  part- 
ners, 197-198 ;  its  collective  name, 
198 ;  in  some  countries  a  legal  person, 
198  ;  influence  on  development  of 
English  law,  198-199 ;  like  a  corporation, 
207 ;  developed  by  state  needs,  207- 
208. 

Societe  en  Commandite,  196. 

Somers  Islands  Company,  the,  209. 

South  Sea  Company,  the,  210 ;  pro- 
posal to  take  over  the  national  debt, 
212-213,218-219;  its  failure,  216  ;  the 
ensuing  panic,  219. 

Special  Assumpsit,  when  it  lay,  76. 

Stakeholder,  remedy  of  winner  to  re- 
cover from  a,  94. 

Star  Chamber,  its  influence  on  the  law 
of  crime  and  tort,  302,  305-306 ;  its 
influence  on  defamation,  336,  338-339. 
340,  342, 361-362 ;  legal  problems  arising 
after  its  abolition,  361-364  ;  its  treat- 
ment of  conspiracy,  379,  380,  382,  385, 


INDEX 


499 


393 ;     its    influence    on    maintenance, 

398;   its  jurisdiction  as  censor  morum, 

407. 
Starkie,  415. 
Statute,  operation  of  a,  which  makes  a 

contract  illegal,  54. 
Statute  Merchant,  arrest  of  debtors  by, 

231. 
Stbersman,  the,  248. 
Stephen,  J.,  310,  318,  320,  322,  337, 340, 

341.  344.  4IO»  4I5.  4l6.  4l8»  441.  442» 

444.  445- 
Stock  Brokers,  214. 
Stock  Exchange,  growth  of  a,  214. 
Stoppage  in  Transitu,  243,  257. 
Stowell,  Lord,  266. 
Straccha,  279,  296. 
Street,  Mr.,   5,  70,   84,  161,  165,  423, 

453- 

Subrogation,  how  used  by  the  creditors 
of  a  company,  204. 

Sue  and  Labour  Clause,  284,  290. 

Suicide,  304. 

Sumner,  Lord,  39,  419,  461. 

Superstitious  Uses,  412-413,  417-418. 

Surgeons,  449. 

Survivorship,  excluded  as  between  part- 
ners, 217. 

Sword  Blade  Company,  the,  215-216. 

Symbolic  Delivery,  118-119. 


Taking,  when  remediable  by  indebitatus 
assumpsit,  95-96. 

Ta VERNE RS,  449. 

Tawney,  Mr.,  in. 

Tenants,  threatened  violence  to,  423. 

Tender,  79-S0. 

Tenterden,  Lord,  37,  see  Abbott. 

Termes  de  la  Ley,  6. 

Thorpe,  C.J.,  423. 

Time  Bargains,  214. 

Time  Policies,  280. 

Tindal,  C.J.,  19. 

Toleration  Act,  the,  405,  410,  411. 

Tort,  encroachments  on  by  criminal 
law,  302  ;  developments  in  law  of,  305 ; 
effect  on  of  combination  of  Star  Chamber 
and  common  law  doctrines,  306;  ex- 
ternal influences,  306-307  ;  growth  of 
the  substantive  law  of,  432  ;  how  dis 
tinguished  from  crime,  306. 

Trade,  contracts  in  restraint  of,  56-62 ; 
the  mediaeval  law,  56-57 ;  law  of  the 
sixteenth  century,  57-58 ;  of  the  seven- 
teenth century,  58-59 ;  change  of  ideas 
at  the  Revolution,  59 ;  restatement  of 
the  law  by  Parker,  C.J.,  60-62;  the 
modern  cases,  62. 

Trade,  how  promoted  by  banking,  178- 
179 ;  organization  of  the  object  of  early 


charters   to  companies  200-202,   2og; 
action  for  imputation  of  unfitness  for, 

349- 
Trade  Disputes,  392. 
Trade  Mark,  counterfeiting  a,  430. 
Traders,   bankruptcy  acts  confined   to, 

237.  241. 

Transport,  insurances  against  risks  of, 
294. 

Treason,  307-322 ;  adherence  to  the 
king's  enemies,  307-308 ;  compassing 
the  king's  death — the  gist  of  the  offence, 
309 ;  mediaeval  interpretations,  309 ; 
legislative  extensions,  309-310 ;  why 
constructive  extension  became  possible, 
310-3 11;  proof  of  the  intent  to  kill,  311- 
312 ;  extensions  made  in  early  seven- 
teenth century,  312-314 ;  development 
in  latter  half  of  the  century,  314-316  ; 
after  the  Revolution,  316-318;  levying 
war — conspiracy  to  levy  war,  318-319; 
distinction  between  levying  war  and 
riot,  319-320,  328;  the  law  after  the 
Revolution,  320-321 ;  Edward  III.'s 
statute  of,  307,  312,  321-322;  the 
statutes  of  1795  and  1848,  321-322 ; 
change  in  the  conception  of,  322  ;  con- 
spiracy to  indict  for,  386-387 ;  mis- 
prision of,  see  Misprision  of  Treason. 

Treason-Felony,  321. 

Treby,  C.J.,86,  91. 

Trespass,  encroachment  on  by  statutory 
misdemeanours,  301-302  ;  application 
of  the  idea  of  negligence  to  453-458, 
465-466  ;  limits  of  its  application,  466- 
468 ;  to  land  or  goods,  liability  for, 
465-468. 

Trinity,  impugning  the  doctrine  of  the, 
411. 

Trusts,  for  anti-Christian  purposes, 
legality  of,  409,  411-412,  414,  416. 

Truth,  no  defence  to  an  indictment  for 
libel,  339. 

Twelve  Tables,  the,  rules  as  to  de- 
famation in,  335. 

Twisden,  J.,  54. 


U 


Underwriting,  278. 

Undue  Influence,  51. 

Unenforceable,  how  distinct  from  void 
and  voidable,  65-66. 

Unitarians,  411-412. 

Unjust  Enrichment,  use  of  indebitatus 
assumpsit  to  remedy,  92-96  ;  see  Quasi 
Contracts. 

Unlawful  Assembly,  definition  of,  324  ; 
nature  of  the  offence,  325-326 ;  evolu- 
tion of  the  law  as  to,  326-327,  329 ; 
duties  of  citizens  in  respect  to,  330- 
331. 


500 


INDEX 


Uses,  doctrine  of  consideration  in  connec- 
tion with,  5,  6. 

Usury,  100-113;  reason  for  usury  laws, 
112-113;  mediaeval  attitude  to,  101 ; 
mediaeval  law  as  to,  101-103;  modifi- 
cation of  the  prohibition  of,  103-106; 
why  it  was  not  wholly  abolished,  106- 
107 ;  the  fifteenth  and  sixteenth  cen- 
tury statutes,  107- 1 10;  characteristics 
of  the  compromise  reached,  no; 
economic  feeling  in  favour  of  greater 
liberty,  in  ;  relief  given  by  equity  and 
the  Council,  in  ;  later  legislation,  111- 
112;  history  of  points  to  a  new  com- 
mercial organization,  112-113;  use  of 
cambium  fictivum  to  evade  the  prohibi- 
tion of,  127;  insurance  contracts  dis- 
guised as  sales  for  the  same  reason, 
274. 


Valentine,  339. 

Valery,  his  suggested  origin  of  bills  ot 

exchange,  134,  135  ;  on  the  origins  of 

insurance,  275. 
Valuable  Consideration,  5. 
Value,   presumption   that  the   acceptor 

of  a  bill  has  received,  143,  167. 
Valued  Policy,  293. 
Vaughan,  C.J.,  72. 
Vaughan-Williams,  L.J.,  463. 
Venditio  Bonorum,  adoption  of  Roman 

system   of  by   the   Italian  cities,  229- 

230. 
Vendor's   Lien,  in   case  of  purchaser's 

bankruptcy,  243. 
Venice,   bank  of,   177,   180,    181 ;    con- 
trasted with  the  Bank  of  England,  188. 
Venue,  difficulties  caused  by  the  rules  of, 

308. 
Verbal  Acceptance,  of  a  bill,  156,  157. 
Vinogradoff,  Sir  Paul,  42. 
Vintners,  449. 
Virginia  Company,  the,  209. 
Void,  Voidable  and   Unenforceable, 

the  distinction  between,  51,  65-66. 
Void   Contract,  promise  to  pay  a  debt 

due  under  a,  31-32,  36-37. 
Voidable   Contract,  promise  to  pay  a 

debt  due  under  a,  26,  27,  31,  37. 
Voluntary  Conveyances,  a  bankrupt's 

can  be  set  aside,  240. 
Voyage  Policies,  280. 


W 


Wagering  Contracts,  56. 

Wagers,  disguised  as  insurances,  280; 
prohibited  at  Genoa,  281 ;  no  legislation 
as  to  such  insurances  in  England,  293 ; 
insurances  against  personal  risks  used 
as  a  disguise  for,  296. 

Walcot,  J.,  473. 

Walmesley,  J.,  389. 

Walsingham,  286. 

Ward,  C.B.,  86. 

Wardship,  feudal,  influence  of  on  law  as 
to  wrongs  to  domestic  relations,  427- 
428. 

Warranty,  breach  of  express  enforced  by 
action  of  deceit,  68,  77 ;  application  of 
this  idea  to  contracts  of  sale  of  goods, 
68-69  ?  implied  warranties,  69-70 ;  basis 
of  the  liability  on,  69-70  ;  in  eighteenth 
century  remedied  by  action  on  the 
contract,  70 ;  effect  of  this,  70  ;  of  title 
and  quality,  70  ;  effect  of  the  breach  of 
a»  77.  78 ;  ex  post  facto,  77. 

Welwod,  248,  250,  251,  252,  264,  267. 

Wife,  how  far  coercion  by  husband  is  a 
defence  to  a  criminal  charge,  443-444. 

Wigmore,  Professor,  477. 

Wild  Animals,  liability  for  damage  done 
by,  469-470 ;  for  their  trespasses,  470. 

Wilde,  B.,  37,  41. 

Willes,  J.,  380,  381. 

Williams,  Serjeant,  73. 

Wilmot,  C.J.,  32,  45,  54. 

Wilson,  his  views  on  usury,  no;  his 
account  of  cambium  siccum,  127. 

Winfield,  Dr.,  387. 

Winnington,  Sir  Francis,  343. 

WlTHINS,  J.,  473. 

Words,  when  an  overt  act  of  treason,  309, 

312,  312-313,  314,  315-316,  316-317; 

action  on  the  case  for,  335,  346-361,  364, 

see  Defamation. 
Workmen's  Compensation  Act,  the,  482. 
Wray,  C.J.,  38g. 

Wrecked  Goods,  the  right  to,  269. 
Wrenbury,  Lord,  418. 
Writ  of  Conspiracy,  the,  385,  386,  388. 
Writings,  when  an  overt  act  of  treason, 

312,  313,  3^-^5>  316-317. 
Wylde,  J.,  453. 


York  Buildings  Company,  the,  215, 


PRINTED    IN    GREAT    BRITAIN    AT    THE    UNIVERSITY    PRESS,    ABERDEEN 


I 


niii^m  <j 


& 


University  of  Toronto 
Library 


DO  NOT 

REMOVE 

THE 

CARD 

FROM 

THIS 

POCKET 


Acme  Library  C»rd  Pocket 
L'nd«f  Pat.  *'Ref.  lata  File" 

Made  by  LIBRARY  BUREAU